SEYMOUR MARTIN LIPSET POLlTiCAL SOCSOLOGEST Thesis for the Degree of M. A. MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY Lee Sloan 1963 THESIS LIBRARY Michigan State University SEYMOUR MARTIN LIPSET POLITICAL SOCIOLOGIST ERne d" Leena: I (Lee) Sloan A THESIS Submitted to the College of Science and Arts of Michigan State University of Agriculture and Apolied Science in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF ARTS Department of Sociology and Anthr0pology 1963 ACKZJLV‘J JED-.31 IEIITS My first debt of gratitude is owed my parents whose best interests were seemingly always transcended in my behalf. Two other primary social groups have been instrumental in sustaining me in all my endeavors as a graduate student, and my indebtedness to them must also be acknowledged. My present family provides the basic core of motivation which keeps me moving towards unattainable gOals. My wife, Mary Lou, has supplied constant and unfaltering encouragement and support. My daughters, Terry, Kelly and Romi, will probably have to wait until they have children of their own to ade- quately realize their role in their dad's educational eXperience. My peers and fellow students, and eSpecially those future sociologists who make quonset 81 their ”home away from home," have provided the vital informal sociali- zation which makes graduate training the rewarding experience it is. Finally, I wish to acknowledge my debt of gratitude to those professional sociologists in whose footsteps it will not be easy to follow. C. Wilson Record and Shared Malelu of Sacramento State College introduced me to the discipline and encouraged me on to graduate school. Men like William Form, David Gottlieb, Charles P. Loomis, and James McKee have contributed immeasurably to my graduate training here at Michigan State University. Dr. Loomis iii warrants special mention for serving as my major professor and for his assistance in the development of this thesis. My indebtedness to Seymour Martin Lipset of the University of California at Berkeley will soon be apparent to the reader. Although I have not yet had the privilege of meeting Dr. Lipset, it's possible his influence is greatest of all. PREFACE In their book, Modern Social Theories, Charles P. and Zena Loomis took a first step prerequisite to the standardi- zation of theoretical concepts within the discipline of sociolog . There they examined the theoretical contributions of seven of the Twentieth Century's major social theorists. They proceeded by utilizing a model called the Processually Articulated Structural Model, or in briefer and more manage- able form, the PAS Model. This model is the result of years of endeavor on the part of Dr. Loomis. The PAS Model is a taxonomic scheme which facilitates the organization of mul- titudinous theoretical conceptualizations in order to allow systematic point by point comparisons between them. The underlying assumption upon which the model is built is that the elements and processes Specified are requisite to the functioning of social systems. In other words, a thorough analysis of the functioning of any and all social systems would require the theorist to be cognizant of these various elements and processes, call them what fig may. The model was designed to take into account both the static and dynamic asaects of social systems. The specified elements provide for the structural aspects while the ele- mental and master or comprehensive processes provide for the functional aSpects of social systems. Elemental pro— cesses are intended to account for or eXplain the Operation of individual elements, while the master or comprehensive processes are intended to eXplain the dynamic interrelation- ships between elements. The model also takes into consideration three of the primary conditions of social action. These are elements which are never completely within society's control and, to the extent to which they are not controlled, therefore operate as conditions to social action. The author of this paper has utilized the PAS Model to aid in the examination of some of the theoretical con- tributions of one of the world's most reputable and contro- versial sociologists. The author makes no claim to have examined all the writings of Seymour Martin Lipset, and a glance at his partial bibliography in the Appendix will go far in eXplaining why he didn't do so. He has, however, examined rather thoroughly and systematically the major books which Lipset has authored--either singly or jointly. Perhaps the most important reading not examined is his most recent monograph, The United States gg §_fl§g Nation. Because of his primary interest in political sociology, certain of the PAS Model categories have been emphasized by Lipset to the relative neglect of others. The categories of Ranking, Controlling, and Norming therefore will be given more attention than others. Although this paper in itself holds value for students of sociology, it is probably the case that it holds most utility as a supplement to the chapters on the other seven vi theorists considered in Modern Social Theories. The reader is also guided to Charles F. Loomis' Sggigl Systems for the initial deveIOpment of the PAS Model. Inasmuch as this is an intensive examination of Lipset's sociological writings, this author has felt obli- gated to allow Lipset to Speak oftentimes (and occasionally at length) for himself. It should also be pointed out to the reader that the author has interpreted 115 primary role to to be that of placing Lipset's theory in terms of the PAS Model--not extensively criticizing that theory. Now it remains only to eXplain the referent "we" found occasionally in the text. That is not merely an "editorial we." Dr. Loomis invited this author to xamine Lipset's contributions to social theory with the thought of potential publication under joint authorship with the Loomises. Therefore the "we" is used in anticipation of a future, potential publication. Although Dr. Loomis has advised in the writing as it now stands, the author accepts full reSponsibility for all that follows. TABLE OF CONTESTS INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ELEMENTS AND EL IENTAL PROCESSES . . . . . . . Knowing . . . . . . . . . Belief (knowledge) as an element . . . . . Cognitive mapping and validation as process Feeling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Sentiment as an element . . . . . . . . . . Tension management as process . . . . . . . Communication of sentiment . . . . . . . . Achieving . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . End, goal, or objective as an element . . Goal attaining and concomitant "latent" activity as process . . . . . . . . . . . Norming . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Norm as an element . . . . . . . . . . . . Evaluation as a process . . . . . . . . . . Dividing the functions . . . . . . . . . . Status- role incorporating both element and process . . . . . . . . . . . Ranking . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Rank as an element . . . . . . . . . . Evaluation of actors and allocation of status-roles . . . . . . . . . . . . . Controlling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Power as an element . . . . . . . . . . . . Decision making and its initiation into action as process . . . . . . . . . sanctioning O O O O O O O O 0 O O O O O O O O Sanction as an element . . . . . . . . . . Application of sanctions as process . . . . FaCilitating O O O O O I O O O C O O O O I 0 Facility as an element . . . . . . . . . . Utilization of facilities as process . . . viii COMPREHENSIVE OR MASTER PROCESSES . . . . . . . . . . 58 Communication . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58 Boundary maintenance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59 Systemic linkage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 Institutionalization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 Socialization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 Social control . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 CONDITIONS OF SOCIAL ACTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70 Territoriality . . . . . . . ._. . . . . . . . . . 70 Size . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70 Time 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 O O O 72 SOCIAL CHANGE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72 NOTES 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O I O O C C O O O O 75 BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83 APPENDIX: BIBLIOGRAPHY OF SEYMOUR MARTIN LIPSET . . 85 ix LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE PAGE 1. CharacteriStic Ideologies and Social Compo- sitions of Democratic and Extremist Group Orientations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 2. Possible Connections Between Democracy, the Initial Conditions Associated with its Emergence, and the Consequences of an Existent Democratic System . . . . . . . . . . 57 INTRODUCTION In reading Lipset, one soon recognizes that the values and beliefs of Lipset, "the man in society," have established guidelines for Lipset, "the student of society." It is not our intent in noting this to cast doubt upon the objectivity of one of America's foremost sociologists, but it is neces- sary to recognize that all social scientists (and other scientists as well) are to some degree influenced as pro- fessionals by their values held as members of society. The rather obvious link between his avowed support of the "democratic socialist movement"1 and the very topics he has chosen for study therefore warrants our mentioning. His first major publication focused upon a study of "the first electorally successful North American socialist movement,"2 the Cooperative Commgnwealth Federation (C.C.F.)3 of Sas- katchewan, Canada. Union Democragy, written with co-authors Martin Trow and James Coleman, was Specifically "aimed at identifying the factors which make for and sustain democracy in private organizations."4 Political Man, wherein Lipset has set forth his "basic intellectual concerns and personal values more fully"5 than in previous publications, centers about a study of democracy as a characteristic of social systems. The principal tOpics discussed are the conditions necessary for democracy in societies and organizations; the factors which affect men's participation in politics, particularly their behavior as voters; and the sources of support for values and movemengs which sustain or threaten democratic institutions. As can be seen, his studies have focused upon the operation of democracy, eSpecially as manifested in the English Speaking and Western EurOpean countries. In Political Man, Lipset concludes by denying that the end of ideology is at hand and by offering a perhaps over- rationalistic justification for his sociological endeavors. He contends that there will be no complete attenuation of the ideological class struggle. Such struggles will continue in the underdeveIOped countries of the world and at the international level. It is only the ideological class struggle within the West which is ending. Ideological conflicts linked to levels and problems of economic deveIOpment and of appropriate political institutions among different nations will last far beyond our life-time, and men committed to democracy can abstain from them only at their peril. To aid men's actions in furthering demo- cracy in then absolutist EurOpe was in some measure Tocqueville's purpose in studying the Operation of American society in 1830. To clarify the operation of Western democracy in the mid-twentieth century may gon- tribute to the political battle in Asia and Africa. By now it should be abundantly clear that Lipset is primarily a political sociologist. He may also be considered to be among the ranking students of social stratification and industrial sociology. The difficulties inherent in a study of politics are many and complex, a fact which has not been prOperly appreciated--especially by political scientists. Lipset has joined Talcott Parsons in criticizing the narrow theo- retical approach of political scientists. He quotes the 3 following from Parsons in support of the argument that the study of politics cannot be treated in terms of a Specifically Specialized con- ceptual scheme . . . precisely for the reason that the political problem of the social system is a focus for the integration of all of its analytically distinguished components, not of a specially differentiated class of these components.8 Parsons' emphasis upon the integration of "analytically distinguished components" serves to introduce two important matters at this time. First, it will not be possible for the authors of this paper to consider a particular PAS Model element (an "analytically distinguished component") in the complete absence of references to other elements. It will be necessary to occassionally refer to that presented in preceding sections and/or to anticipate that which will be stressed in subsequent sections. Secondly, and more impor- tantly, Parsons' emphasis upon integration serves to intro- duce Lipset's concern with the securing and maintenance of a proper balance between conflict and consensus within society. The necessity for the maintenance of a prOper balance between conflict and consensus within society is a central theme in Lipset's writings. He has noted that "although the central concern of the study of politics is the problem of consensus and cleavage, sociologists until fairly recently have been much more involved in studying the con- ditions facilitating cleavage than studying the requisites of political consensus."9 As a rule, social theorists have overemphasized one of the aspects to the relative neglect of the other. Karl Marx was of course most reSponsible for over- emphasizing conflict or cleavage. For him, conflict and consensus were entirely dissociated, as Lipset has observed: To Marx, conflict and consensus were alternatives rather than divergent tendencies that could be balanced within a society. 0n the one hand, he projected con- sensus, harmony, and integration into the communist future . . . ; on the other hand, in the Span of history between the ancient primitive communism and the coming success of the proletarian revolution, conflict or absolutism prevails, and class struggle is the great fact of history. Alexis de Tocqueville was the first to stress the balance between conflict and consensus within a democratic social system, and Lipset is probably the most ardent con- temporary supporter of this thesis. At first glance, Tocqueville's theory seems to be similar to Marx's on the formal level in that both men emphasized the solidarity of social units and the necessity for conflict among these units. (For Marx the units were classes; for Tocqueville, they were local communities and voluntary organizations.) How- ever, Tocqueville, unlike Marx, deliberately chose to emphasize the positive political aSpects of social units which could maintain political cleavage and political consensus at the same time. Together with Marx and Tocqueville, two other classi- cal social theorists have, in Lipset's view, "established the basic concerns of modern political sociology."12 Those two are Max Weber and Robert Michels. Both were primarily concerned with the relationships between bureaucracy and democracy. Weber saw bureaucratization as an inevitable element of industrialized societies, rather capitalistic or 5 socialistic in character. He feared that the growth of the centralized bureaucratic state would lead to the decline of democracy.13 Socialism, for Weber, was simply "the exten- sion of bureaucratic authority to the entire society, resulting in a 'dictatorship of the bureaucrats' rather than of the proletariat."14 Michels Saw oligarchy as inherent in large scale organization, even those founded on democratic principles. He pointed to the advantages of control over organiza- tions for the incumbent leaders, to the political incapacity of rank-and-file members, to the causes of their apathy, and to the pressures on leaders to per- petuate themselves in office. And he saw the pattern of oligarchy within bureaucratic Socialist partiep extended to the society governed by such parties. 5 Lipset traces his intellectual deve10pment primarily to three former teachers and colleagues at Columbia University: Paul Lazarsfeld, Robert Lynd, and Robert Merton. He admits major debts to his colleagues, Juan Linz and Reinhard Bendix. His writings reflect a thorough know- ledge of the contributions of Tocqueville, Aristotle, and such classical sociological theorists as Marx, Weber, Michels, and Durkheim. In his own words, as reported early in his career, My own theoretical framework is derived largely from the sociologists who have been concerned with problems of power, influence, class, organization, social change, and functional analysis. . . . I have not integrated the various theoretical systems into one system. The task of deveIOping and integrating a systematic sociology is one which the entire disciplinf faces and which few persons pretend to have resolved. 6 It would appear that Lipset still subscribes to the same vieWpoint. If it may be said however, that he has one 6 underlying theoretical orientation, then he is essentially a functionalist-~in Merton's sense of the term. Gabriel A. Almond, in a review of Political Man, was critical of Lipset's "haste in theoretical formulation and in the interpretation of findings." In elaboration, Almond continued that: Perhaps an eXplanation for Lipset's haste may be found in the cross pressures which his intellectual heritage imposes on him. Struggling within him is a Weber— Parsons-Merton theoretical impulse, a Lazarsfeld methodological impulse, and a Lynd impulse toward significance and relevance. An harmonious accomodation of these cross-pressures is difficult to attain, and it is to Lipset's credit that he constantly seeks to attain it, and so often succeeds.1 Lipset is not one to ignore the utility of historical analysis, as many contemporary sociologists do. Historical analysis assumes a position of vital importance in each of his major works. In Lipset's opinion, sociological analysis tends to present a static picture, "a description which shows the process at work within the going system, but not the process which enabled the system to reach more or less stable equilibrium."18 Further justifying the role of historical analysis, he called attention to the interplay between historical and sociological analyses. By thus viewing the system as being in an equilibrium which at any point in time has a certain stability, but which could have moved in different directions if some of the factors in the situation had occurred differently, we can see the need to deal with historical materials. It remains for the historical analysis of events which were unique to the ITU’ Ehe International Typographical Union, the subject of study in Union Democracy] to indicate which factors favored the emer- gence and stability of ITU democracy at different points in time, and to Specify the crucial junctign points at which new elements entered the situation.1 In recent years, Lipset has turned increasingly towards secondary analysis, "the study of Specific problems through analysis of existing data which were originally collected for other purposes."20 He has utilized IBM decks loaned him by individual scholars, governmental agencies, public opinion polling agencies, etc., to great advantage. Aside from the obvious pragmatic advantages--e3pecially the economic--Lipset's qualitative and quantitative successes further testify to the virtues of secondary analysis. ELEMENTS AND ELEMENTAL PROCESSES KNOWIN G Belief (knowledge) gg g3 element. The element of belief seems to be implicitly incorporated within a number of central concepts utilized by Lipset. Such concepts as legitimacy, ideological equalitarianism, authoritarianism, and the conceptual ideologies of "left," "right," and "center"--as applied to both democratig and antidemocratic groups--are all concepts which to some degree incorporate the cognitive aSpect. Yet most of these concepts may be more apprOpriately presented in sections following. Lipset eSpecially utilizes the term "belief" in dealing with that which is part of the PAS Model evaluative processes of Norming and Ranking. Cognitive mapping and validation gg proces . The genesis of many beliefs may be traced to a social reality of the historical past. Such beliefs are occassionally perpetuated even after the social realities have been altered. Thus it is that beliefs contrary to reality exert their influence upon social behavior. . . . American workers tend to vote for mildly reformist parties, while European workers normally vote socialist or Communist. Supposedly living in an open-class society, with a deve10ping economy which continually creates new jobs above the manual-labor level, the American worker is presumably more likely to believe in individual opportunity. His EurOpean counterpart, accepting the image of a closed-class society which does not even pretend to offer the worker a chance to rise, is impelled to act collectively for social change. While these sterotypes of the relative degree of social mobility in EurOpe and America do not correSpond Eo reality, their acceptance may well affect voting. 1 Lipset sees the liberalism of intellectuals throughout the world to be partially accounted for by the very concepts utilized by the scientist22 and the intellectual's greater awareness of the power dimension of society.23 Another factor contributing to the American intellectual's liberalism is his perceived status inferiority. What is particularly interesting at this point is the fact that although numerous polls reveal that he is accorded relatively high status by his fellow citizens,24 the American intellectual persists in believing that he is deprived of status justly earned. Other factors contributing eSpecially to the liberalism of American intellectuals will be examined below. Lipset has noted that "each major social stratum has both democratic and extremist political eXpressions."25 It may well be that Lipset has not adequately set forth the factors which account for the differential response of individuals or groups within the various strata. He has emphasized, however, that “the Specific prOpensity of given social strata to support either extremist or democratic political parties . . . cannot be predicted from a knowledge of their psychological predispositions or from attitudes inferred from survey data."26 Elsewhere he has said that "Extremist movements have much in common. They appeal to the disgruntled and the psychologically homeless, to the personal failures, the socially isolated, the economically insecure, the uneducated, unsophisticated, and authoritarian persons at every level of the society."27 In short, extremist movements have their roots in crises eXperienced and shared by individuals and collectivities, whatever their class position. FEELING Sentiment gg an element. It is primarily "the dif- ference between liberal or radical and conservative orien- tations, in the usual meaning of these terms,"28 which accounts for the historic ideological cleavage and its per- sistence within the ITU. These dispositional differences seem to stem from the unique backgrounds and experiences of the individual union members--sources outside the union itself. This goes far in eXplaining the differences in the saliency of the dispositions among union members. The authors of Union Democracy have called this saliency of the liberal or conservative attitudes "ideological sensitivity."29 We will examine below the manner in which social context exerts influence upon the individual's union vote independent of his diSposition toward liberalism or conservatism. 10 The printer's job satisfaction has been an important factor accounting for a high degree of both formal and informal association among printers. "If men like and are interested in their work, they will be more likely than those who dislike the work to associate with others in the occu- pation."3O This high degree of intra-shop and intra- occupational association has played a major role in the persistence of the two-party system within the ITU. Sentiments deriving from extreme hardships may easily persist long after the disappearance of the hardships, as the following quotation illustrates. Lipset was writing of his research eXperiences in the late 1940's, quite some time after the drought and depression years of the 1930's. Saskatchewan is riding the crest of the economic and climatic cycles, but it is still thinking in terms of the 'thirties. As one interviews the residents of rural Saskatchewan today, one cannot help being impressed by their ever-present fear that prOSperity will not last, that a new drought or depression will set them back again. At farmers' conventions, at "bull sessions" in the local stores, the discussion always turns to the control of wheat prices, to crOp insurance, and to the politicians who are Relieved to have power to prevent another catastrOphe.--1 In the section following on Tension management, we will note that extremist religion and authoritarian political attitudes both stem from the same social forces. Even more paradoxically, the same social forces may lead to apathy, which may be seen as a lack of sentiment and involvement. The same underlying factors which prediSpose individuals toward support of extremist movements under certain con- ditions may result in total withdrawal from political activity and concern under other conditions. In "normal" periods, apathy is most frequent among such individuals, 11 but they can be activated by a crisis, eSp ecially if it is accompanied by strong millennial appeals. 32 Tocqueville long ago warned of the dangers of apathy. He was among the first to advocate a "pluralistic" political system, one which would allow an interplay of conflict and consensus. It was his fear that the continued rationaliza- tion of society and the centralization of governmental authority would destroy the social bases sustaining conflict and that the resultant apathy would undermine consensus. Drawing from Tocqueville, Lipset notes that . . . consensus as well would be undermined in the mass society. The atomized individual, left alone without membership in a politically significant social unit, would lack sufficient interest to participate in poli- tics or even simply to accept the regime. Politics would be not only hOpeless but meaningless. Apathy undermines consensus, and apathy was the attitude of the masses toward the state which Tocqueville saw 1% the outcome of an industrial bureaucratic society. Tension management gg process. In his writings, Lipset has eSpecially concerned himself with the concept of authoritarianism. This refers to the tendency of individuals34 to view politics and personal relationships in black- and-white terms, a desire for immediate action, an impatience with talk and discussion, a lack of interest in organizations which have a long-range perSpective, and a readiness to follow leaders who offer a demono- logical interpretation of the evil forces (either religious or political) which are conSpiring against him.35 Lipset sees authoritarianism as an adaptive mechanism resorted to especially by those experiencing frustration as a result of their low position in the stratification system. The social base of authoritarianism rests primarily in 12 the lower classes and stems directly from the normal life experiences of lower class individuals. . . . the lower-class individual is likely to have been eXposed to punishment, lack of love, and a general atmOSphere of tension and aggression since early child- hood--all experiences which tend to produce deep-rooted hostilities eXpressed by ethnic prejudice, political authoritarianism, and chiliastic transvaluational religion. His educational attainment is less than that of men with higher socioeconomic status . . . Leaving school relatively early, he is surrounded on the job by others with a similarly restricted cultural, educational, and family background. Little external influence impinges on his limited environment. From early childhood, he has sought immediate gratifications, rather than engaged in activities which might have long- term rewards . 36 The complex psychological basis of authoritarianism is to be found in the components of an unSOphisticated perSpective: "greater suggestibility, absence of a sense of past and future (lack of a prolonged time perSpective), inability to take a complex view, greater difficulty in abstracting from concrete eXperience, and lack of imagination (inner 'reworking' of experience)."37 Many students are agreed that these components are characteristic of low status individuals. The social base of extremist religion also rests in the lower classes. This suggests that both authoritarianism and extremist religions are products of the same social forces.38 Lipset suggests that fundamentalist religious sects, rather than Operating as centers of political protest, drain off the discontent and frustration which would otherwise flow into channels of political extremism. The point here is that rigid fundamentalism and dogma- tism are linked to the same underlying characteristics, l3 attitudes, and prediSpositions which find another ogt- let in allegiance to extremist political movements. Lipset draws from Sven Rydenfelt in support of this position. Rydenfelt, after conducting social research in Sweden, concluded that "The Communists and the religious radicals, as for instance, the Pentecostal sects, seem to be competing for the allegiance of the same groups."40 Communication g; sentiment. The authors of Union Democracy stressed three factors which operated to increase both the formal and informal associations among printers. All three factors are directly related to the process of communication of sentiment. Probably the most important factor is the status marginality of printers. Historically, printers have been accorded high status among manual workers, due primarily to the necessary prerequisite of literacy among printers.41 DeSpite the status gains of other occupational groups, printers still maintain a high status image of themselves.42 Thus printers perceive themselves as being on the margin-- not as members of the middle-class but among the most skilled and prestigeful within the ranks of manual workers. Everything that we know about the Operation of status distinctions indicates that these distinctions are in large measure maintained by persons with a claim to high status refusing to associate with persons who are defined as being lower. While the printers presumably will tend to reject other manual workers, middle-class persons may tend to reject printers as friends since they are manual workers. In addition, association with middle-class persons may be difficult for some printers since it may mean mingling with people whose educational and cultural level is higher than their own. 14 Consequently printers will tend to associate more with each other than will workers who do not possess this ambiguous status. The intraoccupational association among printers is also increased by the union‘s substitute system. The daily hiring of substitutes to meet the irregular and fluctuating work loads common throughout much of the printing industry is carried out through a lottery. Each substitute draws a numbered ball in order to determine who will work on any particular shift. Thus all substitutes are encouraged to be present for work every day and, if sufficiently pressed financially, for every shift. If, however, a printer is ill or decides to take a day off, he chooses his own replace- ment. Therefore "a substitute's chances for employment are directly related to the number of friends that he has among regular situation holders."44 Finally, the fact that a high prOportion of printers work night hours decreases their opportunities to associate with individuals working more regular hours and at the same time forces printers to associate among themselves in their C O O C O / leisure-time actiVLties.45 ACHIEVING End,_goal g; objective gélgglelement. Although it will be anticipating a subsequent section, it must here be noted that one consequence of the system of stratification is a differential definition of goals. Stratification studies suggest that "inherent in the very existence of a stratification order, of higher and lower valuations of 15 social positions, is the motivation to move up in the social structure if one's position is low, or to retain one's position if it is high."46 Thus it is that goal conflict is inherent in social organization. Democracy, to Lipset, is the best mechanism yet develOped for resolving the conflicting goals of interest groups. In Political Man, Lipset eXpressed at least a partial value judgment when he stated that "A basic premise of this book is that democracy is not only or even primarily a means through which different groups can attain their ends or seek the good society; it is the good society itself in Operation."47 It is only natural that a political sociologist such as Lipset would view political action as a major means of goal achieving. Throughout his writings, Lipset has dealt extensively with goal conflicts and the means by which such conflicts are transcended and resolved through consensus. Goal attaining and concomitant Flaggng" activity ag process. One primary means by which conflict is overcome or lessened is through multiple group affiliation and the resultant "cross-pressures." Lipset has devoted much of his research time to a study of cross-pressures. The desir- ability of establishing and sustaining pluralistic societies lies in the fact that cross-pressures make more probable the proper balance between conflict and consensus. The available evidence suggests that the chances for stable democracy are enhanced to the extent that groups 16 and individuals have a number of crosscutting, politi- cally relevant affiliations. To the degree that a significant proportion of the pepilation is pulled among conflicting forces, its members have an inyerest in reduCLng the intenSity of political conflict.+8 Here also economic development plays a particularly important role in that it increases "the lower classes' exposure.to cross-pressures which reduce their commitment to given ideologies and make them less receptive to extremist ones."49 The latent political functions of secondary organi— zations were eSpecially stressea in Union Democracy. Those functions are essentially two in number: "the external power functions, by which they may Oppose the power of the central body, and the internal functions of increasing the political involvement of their own members."50 These two different functions may be performed by one and the same social organization or by different organizations, or one function may be fulfilled to the relative neglect of the other. In many reSpects, the urban society of the United States represents a type of mass society in which the first function is fulfilled but the second is not. Voluntary associations in the United States do indeed provide counter- vailing sources of power to fulfill the first function, but they operate as primary groups for ggly the small interested and active nucleus of the membership of most organizations. As Lipset, §£,gl., have eXpressed it: "Social relations within the groups which exercise important pressure in politics are often attenuated."51 17 Due primarily to factors of size and the institution- alized decentralization of power, the ITU is able to ade- quately perform both functions whereas most unions and voluntary associations fail to perform either one or the other.52 Lipset has also devoted much study to "leftist" movements, eSpecially those taking place within democratic societies and consequently through democratic means. Leftist voting is seen to be a reSponse to three primary "group needs." 1. The need for security of income . . . 2. The need for satisfying work--work which provides the Opportunity for self-control and self-expression and which is free from arbitrary authority. 3. The need for status, for social recognition of one's value and freedom from degrading discrimination in social relations.53 A review of North American agrarian protest movements reveals that "it was the economic and climatically vulnerable wheat belt that formed the backbone of all the protest movements, from the Independent parties of the 1870's down to the contemporary C.C.F. in Canada."54 Economically, the one crOp wheat belt, which extends through western Canada and the United States, is vulnerable in that it is dependent upon a fluctuating international market and the monOpolistic business practices of the East. It is not absolute poverty as such, but rather the "chronic alternation" between the two extremes that brought about the leftist tendency. Saskatchewan did not follow the normal pattern whereby agrarian radicalism is followed in a few decades by political 18 and economic conservatism. "The oscillating character of the Saskatchewan economy went far toward preventing the emergence of an integrated, conservative rural society."55 It is to be noted that the Socialist Movement of the C.C.F. grew as a latent consequence of the political and COOperative efforts of Saskatchewan wheat farmers to achieve economic stability. To sum up, the first three decades of the twentieth century witnessed the creation of a powerful, organized, class-conscious agrarian movement in Saskatchewan. The wheat farmer, who was situated at the producing start and the consuming end of a highly organized and often monOpolistic distribution system, became convinced that he, as the primary producer of wealth, was being ex- ploited by "vested interests." He deveIOped hostile class attitudes to big business, to the neWSpapers, which he believed served the "interests," and to mer- chants. As a result, a large proportion Of the farming pOpulation supported an agrarian socialistic program designed to eliminate private profits by governmental or COOperative action before an eXplicitly socialist party appeared upon the scene.5 Contrary to general opinion, "democratic reform governments are more a result than a cause of social change."‘7 Once in office, a democratic reform government is faced with the continual problems of maintaining electoral support and Operating through a bureaucracy established by another government with other interests. Thus it is only natural that such reform governments gradually if not immediately give way to bureaucratic conservatism. The growing conser- vatism of reform movements seems to be characteristic of "trade-unions, COOperatives, and left-wing political parties" everywhere.58 The necessity of maintaining electoral support is an eSpecially effective deterrent to social change. 19 The need of a democratic government to retain the sup- port of a majority of the electorate is a powerful weapon in the hands of groups that wish to prevent social change. Any drastic change in basic institutions may endanger the pOpular support of the government. Socialist governments, therefore, have followed the path of least resistance, instituting reforms that meet the least opposition from entrenched interests.5 In elaborating this important point Lipset drew heavily from both Weber and Michels, among others, concluding that Organizations are always started as means of attaining certain value ends. However, organizations become ends in themselves, which often are obstacles in the achieve- ment of the original goals. This does not mean that organized social effort does not secure many of the value ends that it was set up to achieve . . . Gradually, however, every large-scale social organization falls victim to the virus of bureaucratic conservatism, and to the fear th at a further challenge tgo the status quo will injure its power and status NORMING Norm _§ g3 element. Of all the PAS Model elements, that of norms is one of the most important for Lipset. The norms of legitimacy, tolerance, bureaucratic political neutrality, and conformity have been of Special importance for him. That norms constitute an important factor in the determination of behavior is reflected in the following: One would eXpect that . . . trade unionists . . would behave differently within the different value systems which char.cterize different social structures. An American trade-union Operating within the American social structure, with its emphasis on individual achievement, the right of each individual to equality with others, and the norm of democracy, should behave differently from a German union working within the context of a more rigid status system, with greater acceptance of the leadership role, with less concern 20 for the right of the individual compared to the group, and with presumed less emphasis on the norm of democratic control. Similarly, the behavior of two American trade— unions should vary with the composition of their member- ships, in so far as the difference in membership is reflected in different weights and distributions of the crucial norms regarding authority and democracy.61 Iipset has never accepted Robert Michel's "iron law of oligarchy" as a completely deterministic "law." Early in his professional career, in a paragraph that anticipated the writing Of Uniog Democracy, he implied that such a rigid formulation neglected normative alternatives. The justified concern with the dangers of oligarchic or bureaucratic domination has, however, led many per- sons to ignwre the fact that it docs make a difference to society which set of bureaucrats controls its destiny. There are bureaucracies and bureaucracies . . . Bureau- crats are human beings, not automatons. The desire to maintain a given bureaucratic organization is only one of the complex series OF factors determining their actions . . . A deterministic theory of bureaucratic behavior, such as that advanced by Robert Michels or James Burnham, neglects the implications pf an alter- native pattern of bureaucratic reSponse.6 Within the ITU, the norm of Opposition legitimacy goes far in countering the "iron law.” Opposition legitimacy functions within the ITU in Spite of the fact that the union constitution Specifically prohibits formation of Opposition parties.63 The informal ascription of Opposition legitimacy has important consequences for the political system. The acceptance of Opposition "as right and prOper both by the men it is striving to dislodge and by some large prOportion of the membership"64 of the ITU assures the Ooposition of access to the membership through both formal and informal channels of communication. Thus the party in power 21 exercises no absolute monopoly over channels of communica- tion, as is the case in most trade-unions. Contrary to the common belief that "internal party democracy is incompatible with union strength,“65 it is the case that "discontent works to maintain the party system by ensuring turnover in office, while at the same time serving to strengthen rather than undermine the unity and effectiveness of the union in its relations with management and the state."66 Lipset notes that an organized internal Opposition must be ascribed legitimacy if it is to function as a political party. "In the absence of this ascription of legitimacy, an Opposition group constitutes not a party but a faction, with characteristics and functions very different from those of a party."57 He also emphasizes that legitimacy Of Opposition does not assure survival Of the Opposition. If the legitimacy Of opposition guarantees to Opposi- tion elementary rights and freedom Of action, it does n2; guarantee the opposition's survival. Legitimacy guarantees that the incumbents will not use any and all means at their diSposal to crush or repress Opposition; it does not guarantee that ggposition may not wither away from its own weakness. Evaluation ag g process. Lipset sees one of the most important conditions for democracy to be legitimacy--"the degree to which [the political system] is generally accepted by its citizens."69 Stable authority is seen to be the resultant of power plus legitimacy.70 DeSpite its importance as a theoretical concept, "little work has been done using the concept of legitimacy for the analysis of political systems, except that Weber's three categories have been used freely for illustrative purposes."71 Lipset has found it beneficial to differentiate between the legitimacy and the effectiveness of political systems. "While effectiveness is primarily instrumental, legitimacy is evaluative.”2 Lipset, gg gl., in Union Democracy, stressed that legitimacy develoas directly from and is sustained by diverse bases of support and power. The evidence . . . sugeests that a3 internal Opposition gains legitimacy only when i; rests 9g independent and enduring bases 9; support and power which cannot bg destroyed gg repreSQed without seriously weakening the ggion itself.73 Perhaps they eXpressed their viewpoint even more emphatically in the following passage. But we believe it would be misleading to assign to the norms of legitimacy of Opposition an independent and determinative role in the maintenance of the party system in the ITU. Without the diversity of power sources on which it rests, the norm of legitimacy of political Opposition could not by itself maintain the party system as a living political process. Lipset argues that legitimacy is in large measure determined by "the ways in which the key issues which have historically divided the society have been resolved."75 In modern societies, crises of legitimacy occur during a transition to a new social structure, if (1) the status of major con- servative institutions is threatened during the period of structural change; (2) all the major groups in the society do not have access to the political system in the transitional period, 0; at least as soon as they develop political demands. 6 It is significant that even though the political system may be reasonably effective, these two conditions still place the legitimacy of that system in question.77 23 The denial of Opposition legitimacy by a party in power often leads the rank-and-file to deny the legitimacy of that party itself and consequently of the entire political system. The rejection of the democratic game by even a few leaders is a threat to democracy out Of prOportion to the number Of leaders holding such views, even when such men are not able to implement their sentiments through repressive action against the Opposition. It is not the direct attacks which such men may make on the political system that are most dangerous to it, but rather the fact that by Openly repudiating the legiti- macy of the Opposition they invite the rejection of their own political legitimacy (and thgg Of their party) on the part of their Opponents. In an earlier section we commented on the explosive character of the apathetic sector Of the population. It will now be necessary to qualify that somewhat. Although "those sections of the pOpulation that are normally apathetic tend to have authoritarian attitudes and values,"79 analysis of the rise of the Nazi movement suggests "that the most outcast and apathetic sections of the population can be won to political action by extremist and authoritarian parties only after such parties have become major movements, not while they are in their period of early rise."80 This is largely due to the fact that the apathetic reSpond only to the more simple extremist views of politics.81 Just as apathy poses problems for democratic systems, it also poses problems for totalitarian regimes. Totali- tarian states (and autocratic organizations as well) have a Special interest in securing a high level of political participation, for this assures them of "reaching" the pOpulace. 24 But "David Reisman has percentively noted that within a totalitarian society, political apathy may be a major barrier against the complete triumph of the system."82 Ever since Aristotle, men have argued that democracy as a political system is directly related to the state of economic develOpment. Below in another section, we will review Lipset's test of that hypothesis. For Our present purposes, it will suffice to note that (1) there is indeed such a relationship, and (2) economic develOpment is accom- panied by a change from predominantly authoritarian to pre- dominantly democratic beliefs or ideologies among those Of the lower classes. Economic develOpment, producing increased income, greater economic security, and widCSpread higher education, largely determines the form of the "class struggle," by permitting those in the lower strata to develop longer time perSpectives and more complex and gradualist views of politics. A belief in secular reformist gradualism can be the ide logy Of only a relatively well-to-do lower class. Public Opinion surveys from thirteen different countries support Lipset's assertion that lower-class status is associated with authoritarianism. These surveys indicate that "the lower strata are less committed to democratic norms than the middle classes . . ."84 Samuel Stouffer's data from a sample of 5,000 Americans demonstrate that "tolerance increases with moves up the social ladder."8S Education is even a more important determinant of the tendency to hold democratic norms. . . . the most important single factor differentiating those giving democratic reSponses from the others has been education. The higher one's educatifin, the more likely one is to believe in democratic values and sup- port democratic practices. All the relevant studies [from nimerous countries] indicate that education is more significant than either income or occupation.86 Differential degrees Of conformity to dominant societal norms is seen to be related to variations in voting behavior between socioeconomic classes. Group pressures may be directed either toward voting or non-voting. Perhaps paradoxically, "the highest pressure to vote as a symbol of conformity is found where the Objective significance Of the vote is least: in totalitarian 'show' elections."87 Certain ethnic and religious groups encourage voting, while "in parts Of the American South today the norms laid down by the dominant white group for the behavior Of Negroes include a . . . a ’5 prohibition on voting."53 Returning once again to the ideological committment Of the social scientist, this time as regards the Specific norm of bureaucratic political neutrality, Lipset states: How different theoretical and ideological perSpectives lead to differing concrete analysis is illustrated by the concept Of bureaucratic political neutrality, the norm that a member of a bureaucracy is an impartial expert rather than an interested party. Those interested in furthering social change have viewed this norm as a conservative force, since it Operates to force reformist administrations to retain in Office civil servants whose social background and training disposes them to Object to many reformist policies. The same norm, viewed from the perspective of the requisites of a democratic political system, operates to make possible the con- tinuity of democratic government during a turnover in political Offices . . . Inherent in bureaucratic struc- tures is a tendency to reduce conflicts to administrative decisions by eXperts; and thus over time bureaucratiza- tion facilitates the removing of issues from the political arena . . . Thus in many ways the pressures to extend bureaucratic norms and practices constitute an important strength for democratic consensus.89 26 In a controversial interpretation, Lipset has argued that antidemocratic ideologies as well as antidemocratic groups can be more fruitfully classified and analyzed if it is recognized that "left," "right," and "center" refer to ideologies, each of which has a moderate and an extremist version, the one parliamentary and the other extra-parliamentary in its orientation.90 The term "fascism" has been used at various points in time to refer to all three types of extremism. However, "fascism" is most often characterized as "basically a middle- class movement representing a protest against both capitalism and socialism, big business and big unions . . ."91 Closer scrutiny reveals, however, that there are three analytically seoarate and distinct types of fascism which "resemble their democratic parallels in both the compositions of their social bases and the contents of their appeals."92 Or in other words, "A study of the social bases of different modern mass movements suggests that each major social stratum has both democratic and extremist political eXpressions."93 The diagram below has been abstracted from Lipset for the sake of clarification.94 Gabriel Almond has harshly criticized this classifi- cation by Lipset. . . . what Lipset intends here as a contribution to the theory of political movements actually is a contribution to terminological confusion. Right, center, and left, have meant different things in different countries and periods. . . . What he means when he Speaks of right, center, and left extremism, is that the social formations which tend to support the right, left, and center in "normal" periods support different forms of extremism in crisis periods. To Speak of a "center extremism" really strains the imagination. 27 mmwmmau ummas mmmmmao wanwaz mmmmmao wcaxuoz A.mcoaumucmauo . umHEmuuxm cam uwumuooEma Luon HOMM .wmmm Hmaoom mm coauwmoafioo umfiaum \ Emacmaumuauosu5< Emaommm Emacoumm A.%Hmusw5maaumaumuuxmv Hmcowuavmuh aflmmmau Ho EmandEEoo umafimuuxm Ewaamwmpaa A.mumucmEmHaHmm ”mumhwvozv Emaum>ummzoo no zomuooamn Ewaamwoom uaumuooEmQ usw.m amusoo “mm; wmawoaoumw oaumauwuumumso coaumuamauo Hmofluflflom mZOHH 1K / \ mumuonmmudn IR \\\T/ v anumem Hmowuaaoa Eoummm 05Hm> cmwumuaamdwm A.I/III////////// Eoummm mmmao ammo woocommomcoo chofiuapp< mooaosoomaoo manwmmom HmauacH zmemwm uHa cmauwuflamsvm LuHmoB oHEocoom .Eoummm mmmao ammo mcoauancoo 58 develOpment of a certain type of bureaucracy under other conditions which have to be stated if bureaucracy is the focus of the research problem . . . Thus, in a multi-variate system, the focus may be upon any element, and its conditions and consequences may be stated without the implication that we have arrived at a complete theory of the necessary and sufficient conditions of its emergence.193 COMPREHENSIVE OR MASTER PROCESSES Communication. Those social theorists concerned with what has come to be known as the theories of mass society have exerted considerable influence upon Lipset. The most influential among such theorists have been Tocqueville, Lederer, Arendt, Kornhauser, Mannheim, and Selznik. Often- times he prefers to Speak in terms of "political pluralism" rather than in terms of a "mass society." The theory of mass society, as formulated by Emil Lederer and others, states "that a society without a multitude of organizations inde- pendent of state power has a high dictatorial as well as revoluntionary potentialfl"194 Conversely, the potential for stable democracy is greatest within those social systems wherein there are many organizations mediating between the individual and the state. Communication is obviously enough a primary aSpect of the theory. Tocqueville was among the first to recognize the latent political functions of volun- tary organizations seemingly irrelevant to politics pg; 52. According to Tocqueville, voluntary associations serve two primary functions in the maintenance of democratic political systems. "They are a source of new opinions independent of the state and a means of communicating these new suggestions 59 to a large section of the citizenry."19q That participa- tion in voluntary associations is class-linked has been noted by many sociologists.196 Such differential partici- pation in nonpolitical voluntary associations "intensifies the intra-class communications network of the higher strata and weakens in-group communications further down the class ladder."197 The neWSpapers, functioning as channels of communi- cation independent of the state, play a vitally important role in democratic politics. In Tocqueville's words, "The effect of a newsnaner is not only to suggest the same pur- pose to a great number of persons, but also to furnish means for the execution in common of the designs which they may have Cingly conceived."198 It was noted above that the institutionalized legitimacy of Opposition within the ITU served to provide the Opposition with access to the membership through both formal and informal channels of communication, thus prevent- ing a monopoly by the administration. This is also the proper point at which to note that the literacy prerequisite of printers in part enabled them to organize prior to other occupations and to Spearhead the labor press in many unions and in many countries.199 Boundary maintenance. Lipset's central concern as a political sociologist appears to be the study of those conditions which enable a society to maintain a prOper balance between consensus and/or social cohesion on the one 60 hand and cleavage and/or conflict on the other.200 This notion will be more thoroughly examined in the next section on systemic linkage. Lipset has stated that although all institutional arrangements have both integrative and nonintegrative elements, it may be possible to rank them according to their integrative character. It is obvious that the distribution of wealth is the most important source of interest-conflict in complex societies. At the opposite pole is the institution of the family: the integrator par excellence. The second most powerful integrating force . . . is often considered to be religion, which presumably ameliorates the strains arising out of the stratification system by diverting attention from it and adjusting men to their lot in life. However, religion has also been the source of considerable tension in many societies. Institutions which are organized along class lines contribute to both cleavage and integration. In general, the system of stratification creates discon- tent among those who are lowly placed, and is hence a source of cleavage, but it is also the principal means for placing peOple in different positions and motivating them to fulfill their roles. The organization of working-class groups into trade-unions or a labor party, for example, creates a mechanism for the exnression of conflict but, perhaps even more important, integrates the workers into the body politic by giving them a legitimate means of obtaining their wants. 01 Oftentimes, as a response to external attack, the boundary maintenance of a trade-union may be strengthened to the extent that the continued maintenance of a democratic political system is impossible. This suggests to Lipset the necessity of a trade-union's security within its external environment. It appears that a party system is a luxury that only a relatively secure union can afford. Under external attack the importance of internal unity is so great and so overriding as compared with the issues of inter- nal politics that the call for unity, coupled with 61 the definition of internal opposition as traitorous, makes a loyal and legitimate internal Opposition almost impossible.2 The factors accounting for union local autonomy within the ITU are both historical and structural in nature. In the beginning the international was a loose confederation of autonomous locals: there was no powerful central office.203 Through the years, union local autonomy was sustained by the decentralization of the industry and the lack of compe- tition between locals. In addition, local autonomy provided bases of power for the emergence of a two-party system which, in turn, sustained local autonomy.204 Systemic linkage. Although he uses neither term, it is obvious from the above that Lipset sees an important link between the processes of boundary maintenance and systemic linkage. Not only must the conflict among groups be legiti- mized and sustained: such conflict must be transcended through institutionalized means in order that social cohesion exist and the authority of the state itself be legitimized. Systemic linkage is one sociological concept which aids in explaining how societies persist by maintaining a proper balance between consensus and cleavage. Lipset sees conflict as a continuous phenomenon occurring within all societies. Therefore, in order that democratic political systems per- sist, conflict must be legitimized: there must be institu- tionalized processes by which the Opposition meets and com- petes in the political arena with the administration in power. Surprising as it may sound, a stable democracy requires the manifestation of conflict or cleavage so that there 62 will be struggle over ruling Dositions, challenges to parties in power, and shifts Of parties in office, but without consensus--a political system allowing the peaceful "play" Of power, the adherence by the "outs“ to decisions made by the "ins," and the recognition by the "ins" 8f the rights of the "outs"--there can be no democracy. He goes on then to state that, paradoxically, the roots of "legitimate" cleavage are often to be found in conflict itself. "Consensus on the norms of tolerance which a society or organization accepts has often develOped only as a result of basic conflict, and requires the contin- uation of conflict to sustain it."206 In their concluding chapter, the authors of Union Democragy stated that their extensive study of the ITU suggested "that the functional requirements for democracy cannot be met most of the time in most unions or other 2 . . voluntary groups.“ 07 What then of the relationship between oligarchically controlled voluntary associations and the Operation Of democracy at the societal level? We now quote extensively from Lipset in order tha t he might provide his own illuminating answer to that question. (Note the relationship between boundary maintenance and systemic linkage implicit in this passage.) It is noteworthy that the conditions which seem most plausibly related to membership participation and hence to internal democracy in trade-unions and other volun- tary associations . . . are the same conditions which seemingly weaken democracy within the larger society. That is, to the extent that members of an association have a diffuse set of relationships with the organiza- tion, to the extent that a large part of their lives is lived within its influence, to the extent that its members interact with each other, to that degree are the chances for a high level of concern and participa- tion increased. But these same factors isolate the 63 members of the group from cross-pressures add exposure to diverse values and influences, and . . . heighten the intensity of their political beliefs. This again poses a dilemma for us. Integration of members within a trade-union, a political party, a farm organization, a professional society, may increase the chances that members of such organizations will be active in the group and have more control over its policies. But extending the functions of such organizations so as to integrate their members may threaten the larger politi- cal system because it reduces the forces making for compromise and understanding among conflicting groups 0 o o It should be obvious that I do not advocate dictator- ship in private organizations. But it is necessary to recognize that many organizations may never fulfill the conditions for a stable internal democracy and still contribute in important ways to the democratic process in the total society, by providing a secure base for factionalism and real vested interests at the same time that they limit individual freedom within the organi- zation and allow a degree of autonomy of action for both the leaders and the Srganization which may under- mine other social values. 0“ Once again it will be necessary to stress the theory of political pluralism (mass society) in both its negative and positive asoects. Negatively, the potential rise of totalitarianism poses a grave threat in those societies lacking a multitude of crosscutting organizational affilia- tions among individuals. Positively, the potential for stable democracy is enhanced in those societies wherein there exists a multitude of organizations independent of the state and consequently mediating between individuals and the state. In as much as crosscutting bases of cleavage enhance the potential for stable democracy, Lipset has chosen to favor, "all other factors being constant," two-party systems 64 over multiple-party systems, territorial representation over proportional representation, and federalism over the unitary state. It is most appropriate to follow these arguments, point by point, allowing Lipset to sneak for himself as much as is possible. The argument for the two-party system rests on the assumption that in a complex society parties must necessarily be broad coalitions which do not serve the interests of one major group, and that they must not be parties of integration but must seek to win support among groups whigh are preponderantly allied to the opposition party. 09 PrOportional representation, Lipset argues, “increases the chance for more rather than fewer parties and thus] 2 serves democracy badly." 10 Besides, as the German sociologist Georg Simmel has pointed out, the system of electing members of parlia- ment to represent territorial constituencies rather than groups (as proportional representation encourages), forces the various groups to secure their ends within an electoral framework that involves cappern with many interests and the need for compromise. Federalism is desirable over the unitary state in that it "increases the opportunity for multiple sources of cleavage by adding regional interests and values to the others which crosscut the social structure."212 As can be seen, the goal is to institutionalize A I I o - procedures througa which soc1ety must transcend personal and collective interests at lower levels of organization in order that social cohesion be maintained at the societal level. 65 If it is desirable to "create" crosscutting lines of cleavage (e.g., through federalism), it is desirable that such lines of cleavage not merely be superimposed over lines of basic cleavage already existing within society. Thus, qualifying a statement above, federalism does not serve democracy well when it "divides a country across the lines of basic cleavage, e.g., between different ethnic, religious, or linguistic areas, as it does in India and Canada. Democracy needs cleavage within linguistic or religious groups, not between them."213 Lipset has noted that one factor partially accounting for the leftist tendencies of American intellectuals was their "seeming isolation from other sections of the elite . . ."214 The structural source of this perceived isolation is both simple and intriguing. "Quite simply . . . there are, in absolute as well as proportionate terms, more intellectuals in America and they are more widely diSpersed geograwhically than in any other country."215 Thus personal interaction and communication among intellec- tuals is greatly curtailed by the sheer number of intellectuals. Institutionalization. Lipset's sociological perSpective stems from many theorists for whom institu- tionalization was a central concept. In Lipset's own words: Weber saw bureaucratization as an institutional form inherent in all modern societies. To Michels, oli- garchy--government by a small group of persons who co-Opt their successors--was a process common to all large organizations.. Both men tried to demonstrate 66 that even socialist organizations and societies were or would necessarily 2e as bureaucratic and oligarchic as capitalist ones. 1 We have seen that Tocqueville in particular stressed the latent political Functions of the institutions of local government and voluntary associations.217 It is not surprising that institutionalization is as central a concept for Lipset as it was for these impor- tant social theorists. A basic premise of most of his writings is that "democracy requires institutions which support conflict and disagreement as well as those which "218 sustain legitimacy and consensus. The idea of institu- tionalization indeed constitutes an integral part of his definition of democracy.219 Democracy in a complex society may be defined as a political system which supplies regular constitutional opportunities for changing the governing officials, and a social mechanism which permits the largest possible part of the oopulation to influence major decisiogi by choosing among contenders for political office. 0 Voting is undoubtedly one of the most important and fundamental of such democratic norms. Much of his writing is concerned with this "key mechanism of consensus in . . 2 democratic soc1ety." 21 Lipset has seen that the institutionalization of democratic norms is a factor which counters the authoritarian tendencies of certain groups. Once in existence . . . democratic norms become a part of the institutional system . . . But the fact that the movement's ideology is democratic does not mean that its supporters actually understand the implications. The evidence seems to indicate that understanding of and adherence to these norms are highest among leaders 67 and lowest among followers. The general Opinions or predisoositions of the rank and file are relatively unimportant in predicting behavior as long as the organization to which they are loyal continues to act democratically . . . Organized social democracy not only defends civil libertiei gut influences its supporters in the same direction. 2 At one point Lipset notes that a simple measure of the legitimacy functioning within a particular society may be the extent to which national rituals and holidays have become institutionalized as a part of a "secular political culture."223 Socialization. In relative terms, socialization is used less extensively by Lipset than most of the other PAS Model concepts. This is not to suggest, however, that Lipset is unaware of the significance of the concept as a theoretical tool. Speaking of differences in voting, for example, he noted the effects of both "typical" and unique generational exoeriences. Different ages imply variations in life eXperiences and affect left or right political behavior in at least two ways: through generational differences (with the crucial exoeriences of adolescence sometimes shaping the political outlook of an entire age group) and through differences in the typical patterns of social experience associated with differenfizige grouos: adolescence, maturity, and old age. That the family is largely resoonsible for the political socialization of adolescents and young adults is revealed in "hereditary" voting patterns, the tendency for first-voters to vote as their fathers do.225 Socialization seems to be, as was noted above, a most important element accounting for the authoritrrian tendencies 68 of the lower classes. Lipset concurs with Bronfenbrenner, who reports that "the most consistent finding" in studies of child-rearing patterns is the "more frequent use of physical punishment by working-class parents . . ."226 Such find- ings have been complemented "by the 'inding of two investi- gations in Boston and Detroit that physical punishments for aggression, characteristic of the working class, tend to increase rather than decrease aggressive behavior."227 Authoritarianism seems much less prevalent among the higher educated and, conversely, the norm of tolerance is more often adhered to among the higher educated. "The higher one's education, the more likely one is to believe in democratic values and support democratic practices. All the relevant studies indicate that education is more sig- nificant than either income or occupation."228 Socialization was seen to play a particularly significant role within the ITU. Geqerally speaking, "in most unions one of the principal factors which Operate to perpetuate incumbent power is the administration's almost complete monOpoly of the chances For learning political 229 Within the ITU, however, and administrative skills." the status of the occupation, the relatively high educa- tional level of its members, and the extensively developed network 0“ secondary organizations within the union have all Operated so as to supply the ITU membership with ample Opportunities to learn administrative skills. Thus there is within the ITU a wide distribution of political skills 69 among its membership. Here again is another instance of institutionalized democracy furthering its own cause, for "In a system which provides for regular turnover in office, union office itself becomes a training ground for opposition activists and leaders."230 Social control. Lipset's concern with the maintenance of a proper balance between conflict and consensus seems to imply that the social system should, paradoxically, both counter deviancy and allow for it. Lipset subscribes to Merton's proposition that that which may be dysfunctional for one system may well be functional for another system.231 . . such phenomena as the Tory worker or the middle- class socialist are not merely deviants from class patterns, but basic requirements for the maintenance of the political system. A stable democracy requires a situation in which all the major political parties include supporters from many segments of the pOpulation. A system in which the support of different parties correSponds too closely to basic social divisions cannot continue on a democratic basis, for it reflects a state of conflict so intense and clear-cut as to rule out compromise. The deviance of individuals, in other words, Operates so as to prevent the formation of "deviant" parties (which would tend to intensify group cleavage) and to temper emotions within the political realm of the society. It may well be that deviancy, paradoxical though it seems, con- tributes to consensus. As has been indicated above, "cross-pressures result- ing from multiple-group affiliations or loyalties account for much of the 'deviation' from the dominant pattern of a 7O given group. Individuals who are subject to pressures driving them in different political directions must either “233 A high degree of deviate or 'escaoe into apathy.‘ multiple-group affiliation leads to a situation in which most individuals can neither concur wholeheartedly in the actions of "their" party nor disapprove entirely of the actions of the "opposing" party. In accordance with the differential saliency individuals ascribe their multiple- group affiliations, they are constantly deviating from "exnected" patterns of behavior. In doing so, they assist in the maintenance of democracy. CONDITIONS OF SOCIAL ACTION Igrritoriality. Geographical isolation has been shown to be a major factor accounting for a high degree of leftist political participation. Communist and socialist parties generally receive strong support from miners, sailors, fishermen, lumbermen, steeoshearers, and long- shoremen.234 These workers oftentimes live in communities in which the restraining effects of cross-pressures are at a minimum. In addition, the nature of their employment accounts for a high degree of economic insecurity, a factor which we have seen to be an independent source of leftist voting.235 §igg. The condition of size was of course a crucial consideration of both Weber and Michels in their studies of bureaucracy. It would seem that the efficient operation of 71 large-scale organizations demands bureaucratization. And as we have seen, as regards labor unions, "The price of increased union bureaucracy is increased power at the top, decreased power among the ordinary members."236 Lipset has observed that the size of both industrial plants and of cities correlates with leftist voting.237 Just as was the case with the "isolated" industries, large industrial plants make "for a higher degree of intra-class communication and less person 1 contact with people on higher economic levels."238 In Union Democracy, it was demonstrated not only that printers in the larger shOps were more likcly to participate in union politics than were printers in small shops but that this was the case "independently of whether they participate in the printers' occupational community."239 A factor which goes far in eXplaining this is the greater degree of voluntariness of personal interrelationships in the larger shoos. This voluntariness is largely a conse- quence of the simple fact that there are more men from which to choose one's companions.240' In the large shOps there is greater possibility of forming cliques character- ized by homogeniety of political views. In the small sheps, however, there is more necessity to de-emphasize union politics. . . . a small group, in order to preserve good inter- personal relations and solidarity on matters of importance to it, need not and cannot enforce con- sensus with regard to all values and attitudes held by its members. A group may much more easily exert 72 pressure on its members to reduce their interest or involvement in activities and attitudes which are peripheral to the group's own functioning and which may pl.“ ce a strain on solidarity if introduced into it. The value to the group of reducing the saliency of issues upon which group consensus does not exist is clear: what is a matter of relatigg indifference is not a source of internal cleavage. Time. The prevalence of night work within the print- ing industry is another factor in part accounting for a high degree of association among printers. Night work Operates so as to brea R up normal leisure patterns. There are a number of processes which underlie the prOpensity of night workers to associate with printers. First, we would suggest that the day worker is subject to the structured pulls of mass entertainment, of neighborhood org nizations, and of nonprinter friends away from the printers' community, while night workers on all these counts are subject to a push toward the printers' community. Thus while night workers take less part in nonprinter organizations, they take more part in organizgzions associated 2.ith printing than do day workers. In addition, night employment removes the printer from normal family relationships.243 Conflicting schedules tend to pull the printer toward his printer friends who also have difficulty conforming to normal patterns of family activities. Also of importance is the more leisurely pace of night work as compared to that of day work. The relaxed atmOSphere accompanying night employment greatly facilitates socializing on the job.244 SOCIAL CHANGE The subject of social change has been touched upon at numerous points above. It will be recalled that economic development was generally seen to have a liberalizing effect 73 upon social values, while bureaucratization generally was seen to operate as a deterrent to social change. At another point, Lipset stressed the desirability of the gradual intro- duction of the lower classes into the electoral process. In attempting to eXplain social change, Lipset occa- sionally places great emphasis upon the effects of histori- cally unique phenomena. Thus he interpreted the farmers' socialist movement in Saskatchewan to be the result of long years of subordination to eastern economic powers culminated by the drought and depression. Likewise the confederation movement of local unions in the early years of the ITU went far in accounting for the emergence of divergent and indes- tructible sources of power within the union. At other times Lipset argues that complex social characteristics are best considered to have multi-variate causation and consequences. Thus the conditions leading to and resulting from democracy were many and the inter— relation between taose conditions was ascribed a complexity which created many methodological difficulties for the social researcher. Regardless of whether he stresses unique or multi— variate causation, however, he generally Operates within the functionalist framework. He sees social systems opera- ting within a dynamic equilibrium possessing the potential of moving in numerous directions depending upon the influence of the causative factors. 74 In closing, we may note that Lipset argues that major social and political changes have led to either an ideological convergence or an end to ideology--within the Western democratic countries. (We noted above that Lipset sees the ideological class struggle continuing in the under- developed countries and on the international level.) The characteristic pattern of stable Western democracies in the mid-twentieth century is that they are in a "post- politics" phase--that is, there is relatively little difference between the democratic left and right, the socialists are moderates, and the conservatives accept the welfare state. In large measure this situation reflects the fact that in these countries he workers have won their fight for full citizenship. NOTES 7S 76 NOTES 1. Seymour Martin Lipset, Agrarian Socialism (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1950), p. xiv. Hereafter designated as AS. 2. Ibid., p. 3. 3. The C.C.F. has in recent years formally joined forces with certain labor organizations in Canada and now is effective as a national political party known as the N.D.P., the New Democratic Party. 4. Seymour Martin Lipset, Martin Trow, and James Coleman, Union Democrac (Garden City, New York: Doubleday and Co., Inc. , 1962), p. 464. Hereafter designated as UD. 5. Seymour Martin Lipset, Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics (Garden City, New York: Doubleday _and Co., Inc. , 1960), p. 10. Hereafter designated as PM. 6. Ibid., p. 9. 7. Ibid., p. 417. 8. Talcott Parsons, The Social System (Glencoe: The Free Press, 1951), pp. 126- 127:; as cited in Seymour Martin Lipset, "Political Sociology," in Robert K. Merton, Leonard Broom, and Leonard S. Cottrell, Jr. (Eds. ), Sociology Toda : Problems and Prospects (New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1959), p. 33. This articlefifiereafter designated as PS. 9. Ibid., pp. 83-84. 10. Ibid., p. 84. 11. Ibid., p. 87. 12. PM, p. 30. 13. Ibid., p. 36. 14. Ibid., pp. 29-30. 15. Ibid., p. 30. 16. AS, p. xiv. 17. Gabriel A. Almond, in a review of Political Man in6American Sociolo ical Review, Vol. 25, No. 5 (October, 19 O , p. 53 18. up, p. 441. 19. Ibid. 20. Seymour Martin Lipset and Reinhard Bendix, Social Mobility in Industrial Society (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1960), p. ix. Hereafter designated as SM. 21. PM, p. 253. 22. Ibid., pp. 319-320. 23. 25. 27. 29. 31. 33. 35. 36. 38. 40. Kommunismen PM, o. 319. 24. Ibid., p. 131. 26. Ibid , p. 175. 28. Ibid., p. 355. 30. AS, p. 101. 32. Ibid , p. 27. 34. Ibid , pp. 120-121. Ibid., p. 120. 37. Ibid., p. 106. 39. Ibid., Ibid., UD, p. Ibid., PM. 99- Ibid., Ibid., As quoted in Ibid., p. 106. i Sverige. 77 pp. 323 ff. p. 101. 354. p. 136. 121-122. p. 101. 115. 108. p. p. See Sven Rydenfelt, _ fig Samhallsvetenskaplig Studie. (Kund3 Gleerupska Universitetsbokhandeln, 1954). Or see w. Phillips Davison's extensive review of Sven Rydenfelt, which appeared in the Public Opinion (1954-55), pp. 375-388. 41. 43. 44. 46. 48. 50. 52. 54. 56. 58. 60. 62. 64. 66. 68. UD, pp. 120-121. .1219.. 121s.. SM, p. UD, p. LEiQ-. AS, p. 42. pp. 121-122. p. 158. 45. 203. 47. pp. 88-89. 49. 90. 51. p. 91. 53. 10. 55. p. 71 57. p. 70. 59. p. 286. 61. 271. 63. p. 270. 65. p. 305. 67. p 294. 69. Ibid., uarterl , Quote is on p. Vol. 18 p. 123. pp. 153-157. 403. p. 65. . 232. 29. 221. p. p. p. 251. 389. 290. 304. 270. p. p. 39. 70. 72. 74. 75. 77. 79. 81. 82. 78 PM, p 39. 71. PS, p. 108. PM, o. 77. 73. UD, pp. 273-274. Ibid., pp. 287-288. PM, p. 77. 76. Ibid., p. 78. ‘IQLQ., p. 80. 78. UD, p. 282. PM, p. 151. 80. .1p;g., p. 150. Ibid., pp. 151-152. Ibid., p. 216. See David Riesman, "Some Obser- vations on the Limits of Totalitarian Power, " in Individualism Reconsidered (Glencoe: The Free Press, 83. 85. formit 1 55 , eSp. 86. 88. 89. 91. 93. 95. 96. 98. 100. 102. 104. 106. 108. 109. 110. and Ibid., p. 61. Ibid. See Samuel Civil Liberties (N p. 9. PM, p. 56. 1954), pp. 1 ‘ 5- 84. Ibid., p. 104. A. Stouffer, Communism, Con- ew York: Doubleday and Co. , 87. Ibid., p. 202. Ibid., pp. 202-203. PS, p. 102. 90. PM, p. 173. Ibid., p. 134. 92. Ibid., p. 132. Ibid., p. 131. 94. ,Lgid., chap. V. Almond, 22. 915., p. 753. PM, p. 298. 97. Ibid., p. 368. .121g., p. 238. 99. SM, p. 1. PS, p. 85. 101. Ibid., pp. 86-87. SM, p. 1 103. PM, p. 368. SM, p. 64. 105. Ibid., pp. 265-266. Ibid., p. 269. 107. .19;g., p. 273. Ibid , pp. 14-16. Ibid., pp. 16-17. Ibid , pp. 1-2. 79 111. SM, 9. 77. 112. Ibid., p. 76. 113. Ibid., p. 77. 114. Ibid., pp. 66-67. 115. Ibid., pp. 67-68. 116. Ibid., p. 74. 117. Ibid., p. 65. 118. Ibid., pp. 68-69. 119. Ibid., p. 57. 120. Ibid., p. 60. 121. Ibid., p. 63. 122. Ibid., pp. 62-63. 123. Ibid., p. 11. 124. Ibid., p. 165. 125. As quoted in SM, p. 199. See P. F. Lazarsfeld, Ju and und Beruf, Vol. 8 of uellen und Studien zur Jugend- kunde (Jena: G. Fischer, 19 1 . 126. AS, p. 179. 127. Ibid., pp. 192-193. See also Robert Michels, Political Parties (Glencoe: The Free Press, 1949), pp. 260- 262. 128. PM, pp. 243-244. 129. AS, p. 196. 130. Ibid., p. 198. 131. PM, p. 242. 132. Ibid., p. 248. D. 133. Ibid., p. 64. 134. Ibi ., p. 66. 135. See Dewey Anderson and Percy Davidson, Ballots d the Democratic Class Struggle (Stanford: Stanford Uni- ersity Press, 19437. 136. pm, p. 220. 137. Ibid., pp. 223-224. < 138. Ibid., p. 285. 139. UD, p. 14. 140. PM, p. 31. 141. Ibid., p. 34. See Manning Dauer, The Adams Federalists (Baltimore: The Johns HOpkins Press, 19535. 142. SM, pp. 77-78. 143. UD, p. 239. 144. Ibid., pp. 246-247. 145. PM, pp. 232-236. 146. UD, p. 8. 147. .LQ;§., p. 240. 80 148. Reinhard Bendix and Seymour Martin Lipset (Eds.), Class, Status and Power (Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press, 1953), p. 13. 149. PM, p. 357. 150. See Robert S. Lynd, "Power in American Society as Resource and Problem," in Arthur Kornhauser (ed.), Problems 9; Power lfl American Society (Wayne State Univer- sity Press, 19575, pp. 9-10; and Talcott Parsons, "The Distribution of Power in American Society," World Politics, Vol. 10 (1957), p. 139. 151. PS, pp. 105-106. The internal quote is from Parsons, _p. cit., p. 139. 152. Ibid., pp. 105-107. 153. Ibid., p. 106. 154. Ibid. 155. AS, p. 267. 156. PS, p. 92. 157. PM, p. 220. 158. PS, p. 92. 159. PM, pp. 306-307. 160. I;Qid., p. 182. 161. PS, p. 95. 162. PM, p. 218. 163. Ibid., p. 219. 164. Ibid., p. 179. 165. Ibid., p. 203. 166. ,1p;g., p. 205. 167. UD, p. 13. 168. Ibid., p. 8. 169. Ibid., pp. 8-9. 170. Ibid., p. 9. 171. Ibid. 172. Ibid., p. 10. 173. Ibid. 174. Ibid., p. 12. 175. Ibid., p. 464. 176. PM, p. 38. 177. UD, p. 274. 178. Ibid., pp. 15-16. 179. Ibid., p. 16. 180. PM, p. 259. 181. Ibid., p. 260. 182. UD, p. 288. 183. Ibid., p. 38. 184. See eSpecially fn. 6, pp. 40-41, UD. 193. 195. 196. 81 PM, pp. 230-201. Ibid., p. 201. 187. UD, pp. 60-69. Ibid., p. 64. 189. PM, p. 46. Ibid., pp. 46-47. Ibid., p. 74. 192. Ibid., p. 74. Ibid., p. 75. 194. UD, p. 82. Ibid., p. 85. See eSpecially Bernard Barber, "Participation and Mass Apathy in Associations," in A. W. Gouldner, (ed.), Studies ig_Leadership (New York: Harper & Bros., 1950), pp. 197. 198. PM, p. 195. As quoted in UD, p. 83. See Alexis de Tocque- ville, Democracy in America (New York: Alfred A. KnOpf, Inc. 1945), pp. 376-386? ' ' 199. 200. UD, pp. 29-32. See eSpecially his article, "Political Socio- logy," in Sociology Today (PS). 201. 203. 204. 206. 208. 209. 210. 212. 214. 216. 218. 219. definitions the same. PM, p. 40. 202. UD, p. 292. Ibid., pp. 18 ff. H bid., p. 412. 205. PM, p. 21. Ibid., p. 22. 207. UD, p. 452. PM, pp. 396-397. Ibid., pp. 90-91. Ibid., p. 91. 211. Ibid. Ibid. * 213. Ibid., pp. 91-92. Ibid., p. 330. 215. Ibid. Ibid., p. 29. 217. Ibid., p. 27. Ibid., p. 403. Although Lipset advances many variously worded of democracy, the ideas eXpressed are virtually 220. 221. Part II. 222. 224. 226. PM, p. 45. PS, p. 92. PM, p 128 223. Ibid , p. 264. 225. As quoted in Ibid., p. 114. See also PS, pp. 92-98 and PM, Ibid., p. 80. Ibid., p. 212. See Urie Bronfen- brenner, "Socialization and Social Class Through Time and E. Maccoby, T. M. Newcomb, and E. L. Hartley 83:8, Holt, 227. 229. 231. 232. 234. 236. 238. 239. 241. 242. 243. 244. " in E. Readin s in Social Psychology (New York: 1958), p. 419. PM, p. 114. 228. UD, p. 260. 230. See PM, p. 31, fn. 17. Ibid., p. 31. 233. Ibid., p. 87. 235. UD, p. 8. 237. Ibid., p. 252. UD, p. 171. 240. ,Lbig., pp. 186-187. .191Q., p. 155. Ibid., pp. 155-157. 245. Ibid., p. 157. Henry Ibid., p. 56. Ibid., p. 264. Ibid., pp. 31-320 Ibid., pp. 232-236. PM, pp. 249-252. 179. PM, p. 92. B IBL I OGRAPHY BIBLIOGRA H Almond, Gabriel A. A review of Political Man in American Sociological Review, Vol. 25, No. 5 (October, 1960), pp. 753-7540 Bendix, Reinhard and Seymour Martin Lipset (eds.). Class, Status and Power. Glencoe: The Free Press, 1953. Lipset, Seymour Martin. Agrarian Socialism. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1950. . Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics. Garden City: Doubleday & Co., Inc., 1960. . "Political Sociology," in Robert K. Merton, 2; al., (eds.). Sociology Today: Problems and PrOSpects. New York: Basic Books, Inc., 1959, pp. 81-114. , and Reinhard Bendix. Social Mobility 1g Industrial Societ . Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1960. , Martin Trow, and James S. Coleman. Union Democracy. Garden City: Doubleday & Co., Inc., 1962. Loomis, Charles P. Social Systems. Princeton, New Jersey: D. Van Nostrand Co., Inc., 1960. , and Zona K. Loomis. Modern Social Theories. Princeton, New Jersey: D. Van Nostrand, Co., Inc., 1961. APPENDIX 85 86 APPENDIX BIBLIOGRAPHY OF SEYMOUR MARTIN LIPSET BOOKS AND MONOGRAPHS: Agrarian Socialism. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1950. Class, Status and Power. (With Reinhard Bendix, eds.) Glencoe: The Free Press, 1953. Culture and Social Character. With Leo Lowenthal, eds.) New York: The Free Press, 1961. Labor and Trade Unions. (With Walter Galenson, eds.) New York: John Wiley, 1960. Pre'udice and Society. (With Earl Raab) New York: Anti- Defamation League, 1959. Political Man: The §pcial Bases of Politics. New York: Doubleday, 1960. Social Mobilit 1Q Industrial Society. (With Reinhard Ben ix Berkeley: University of California Press, 1959. Sociolo : The Progress 9f1§ Decade. (With Neil Smelser, eds.§ Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 1961. Union Democrac . (With Martin Trow and James S. Coleman) Glencoe: The Free Press, 1953. The United States gglg New Nation. Berkeley: Research Group in Comparative Development, Institute of Industrial Relations, University of California, 1962. ARTICLES: "An Aging POpulation in an Industrial Society: Sociological ASpects," in Harold E. Jones, ed., Research 9p Aging (Pacific Coast Committee on Old Age Research, Social Science Research Council, 1950), pp. 63-66. "American Intellectuals: Their Politic and Status," Daedalus, 88 (Summer 1959), pp. 460-486. "The American Voter," Encounter (August 1956), pp. 55-62. "Aristocracy in America," Commentary (December 1958), pp. 534-37. "The British Voter," I, II, III, The New Leader (November 7 and 21, 1960; February 6, 1961). "Bureaucracy and Social Reform," Proceedings of the Pacific Coast Sociological Society, in Research Studies, State College of Washington, 17 (1949), pp. 11-17. (with Neil Smelser), "Change and Controversy in Recent American Sociology," British Journal 2: Sociology, 12 (1961), pp. 41-51. "A Changing American Character?" in S. M. Lipset and Leo Lowenthal, eds., Culture and Social Character (New York: The Free Press, 1961), pp. 136-171. (with Natalie Rogoff), "Class and Opportunity in EurOpe and the U. 8.," Commentary (December 1954), pp. 562- 568. "Comments on 'The Impact of Income Security Upon Individual Freedom' by Barbara Wootton, " in James E. Russell, ed., National Poligies for Education, Health and Social Services Gar en City: Doubleday and Co. 195 5), p . ms. 04. ’ (with Hans Zetterberg), "A Comparative Study of Social Mobility, Its Causes and Consequences, " PROD, Political Research: Organization Design, 2 (September 1 5 pp. 7-11. "Democracy and the Social System, " in Harry Eckstein and Klaus Knorr, eds., Asgects Lf Internal War (tentative title) (New York: The Free Press, forthcoming). "Democracy and Working-Class Authoritarianism," American Sociological Review, 24 (1959), pp. 482- 502. "Democracy in Alberta," The Canadian Forum (November and December 1954), pp. 175-177, 196-198. "Democracy in Private Government " British Journal g; Sociology (March 1952), pp. 47- "Democracy in the International Typographical Union, " in Yearbook of the American Philoso hical Societ , 1955, (Philadelphia: 195 , pp. 211-218. "The Department of Sociology," in R. Gordon Hoxie, 25 al., History Lf the Faculty Lf Political Science, Columbia University+(New York: Columbia University Press, 1955), pp. 284- 303. 88 "The Egghead Looks at Himself," New York Times Magazine (November 17, 1957), pp. 22, 104-107. "Equal or Better in America, " Columbia University Forum, 4 (Spring 1961), pp. 17- 21 (earlier version published as "A Conflict of American Ideals, " The Listener, November 10, 1960, pp. 821- 823. "Estratificacao e Politica nos Estadoes 4Unidos, " Revista de Direito Publicae Ciencia Politica,4 (1961), pp. 83—_ 104} "European Traditions and American Sociology," Commentary (December 1955), pp. 568-570. (with F. T. Malm), “First Jobs and Career Patterns," American Journal of Economics and Sociology (April 1955), pp. "The Fuss About the Eggheads," Encounter (April 1957), pp. 17-21. (with Reinhard Bendix), "Ideological Equalitarianism and Social Mobility in the United States, " in Transactions 9; the Second World Congress Lf Sociology, II (London: Izternational Sociological Association, 1954), pp. 34- 5 "Harriet Martineau's America: An Introductory Essay," Introduction to Societ in America by Harriet Martineau, ed. by S. M. Lipset (Neww York: Doubleday- Anchor, 1962). (with R. Bendix and F. T. Malm), "Job Plans and Entry into She Labor Market, " Social Forces (March 1955), pp. 224- 33. (with Reinhard Bendix), "Karl Marx’ Theory of Social Classes," in R. Bendix and S. M. Lipset, eds., Class, Staggg and 2.9.1132: pp. 26‘45 o "The Law and Trade Union Democracy, " Virginia Law Review, 47 (1961), pp. 1- 50. "Leadership and New Social Movements, " in Alvin w. Gouldner, ed., Studies in Leadershi (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1950), pp. 34? 362. "Michels' Theory of Political Parties," Introduction to Political Parties by Robert Michels (New York: Collier Paperbacks, 1962). (with Joan Gordon), "Mobility and Trade Union Membership,“ in Class, Status and Power, pp. 491-500. 89 "Opinion Formation in a Crisis Situation," Public QQinigB Qparterly (Spring 1953), pp. 20-46, "Party Systems and the Representation of Social Groups," European Journal 9; Sociolo , 1 (1960), pp. 50-85. "The Political Animal: Genus Americanus " Public Opinion Quarterlz, 23 0959-30), pp. 575 SE. """"‘ "Political Participation and the Organization of the COOpera- tive Commonwealth Federation in Saskatchewan," Canadian Journal 9; Economics and Political Science (May 1§58$, pp. 191-208. "The Political Process in Trade Unions: A Theoretical Statement," in Morroe Berger, 2; al., eds., Freedom and Control 3Q Modern Societ (New York: D. Van Nostrand Company, 19555, pp. 8 -1 4. "Political Sociology," in Robert K. Merton, et al.& Sgciolggy Today (New York: Basic Books, 1959), pp. 81-11 (with Reinhard Bendix), "Political Sociology - A Trend Report and Bibliography," Egrrent Sociology, (1957), pp. 79- 169. "Political Sociology 1945-1955," in Hans Zetterberg, ed., Sociolo in The U.S.A. (Paris: UNESCO, 1956), pp. 33-55. "Polling and Science," Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science (May lgzg), pp. 237:250. "Polling and Science II," Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science (August 1950), pp. 323:429. (with Nathan Glazer), "The Polls on Communism and Conformity," in Daniel Bell, ed., The New Ameriggg Right (New York: Criterion Books, 1955;, pp. 141-165. (with Paul Lazarsfeld, A. Barton and J. Linz), "The Psychology of Voting: An Analysis of Political Behavior," in Gardner Lindzey, ed., Handbook 9: Social Ps cholo , II (Cambridge, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 15555, pp. 112%- 11 5. "The Radical Right," British Journal 2; Sociologz (June 1955), pp. 176-209. (with Martin Trow), "Reference Group Analysis and Trade Union Wage Policy," in Mirra Komarovsky and Paul Lazars- feld, eds., Common Frontiers in Social Sciences (Glencoe: The Free Press, 19577, pp. 391-511. 90 "Religion in America," Columbia University Forum (Winter 1958—1959), pp. 17-210 "The Rural Community and Political Leadership in Saskatchewan," Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science (August 1947), ppt‘h1o-428. "Socialism - Left and Riiht - East and West," Confluence (Summer 1958), pp. 1 3-192. (with Reinhard Bendix), "Social Mobility and Occupational Career Patterns: I, Stability of Job Holdin 3," American Journal 9; Sociology (January 1952), pp. 36 -374. (with Reinhard Bendix), "Social Mobility and Occupational Career Patterns: II, Social Mobility," American Journal 2: Sociology (March 1952), pp. 494-503. "Social Mobility and Urbanization," Rural Sociology (Sept.- Dec. 1955), pp. 220-228. (with R. Bendix and F. T. Malm), "Social Origins and Occu- pational Career Patterns," Industrial and Labor Relations Review (January 1954), pp. 255-251. "Social Status and Prejudice," Commentary (May 1950), pp. 475-479. (with Reinhard Bendix), "Social Status and Social Structure: A Re-Examination of Data and Interpretation, I," British Journal 2; Sociolo (June 1951) pp. 150-168; Ibid. (September 19515, II, pp. 230-254., "Social Stratification and Ri ht-Wing Extremism " British Journal gg‘ggciology, 10 1959), pp. 346-38 . "Social Stratification and the Analysis of American Society," The Voice of America Forum Lectures, Behavioral Science Series 13 (washington: 19515, pp. 1-10 (separate pamphlefy. "A Sociologist Looks at History," Pacific Sociological Review (Spring 1958), pp. 13-17. “Some Social Requisites of Democracy," American Political Science Review (March 1959), pp. 69-105. "Some Statistics on Bigotry in Voting," Commentary, 30 (1960), pp. 286-290. "The Sources of the 'Radical Right'," in Daniel Bell, ed., The New American Right (New York: Criterion Books, 19557, pp. 165-234. 91 "Stability in the Midst of Change," in The Social Welfare Forum&-T1959 (:{ew York: Columbia University Press, 1959), pp. 1 "The Surprising Effect of McCarthyism on 'The Academic Mind'," Columbia University Forum (Fall 1958), pp. 25-29. "Le syndicalisme americaine et les valeurs de la societe americaine," Sociologie g2 Travail, 2 (1961), pp. 161- 181. (with Hans Zetterberg), "A Theory of Social Mobility," in Transactions of The Third World Congress of Sociology, Vol. III (London: International Sociological Association, 1956), op. 155-177. (with Martin Trow and James S. Coleman), "Trade Union Democracy and Secondary Organization," in William Petersen, ed., American Social Patterns: Five Studies (New York: Anchor Books, 1955), pp. 171- 218. (with Daniel Bell) issue editor and co-author of introductory and concluding essays, "Trade Unions and Minority Problems, " Journal of Social Issues, Vol. IX, No. l 1953) "Trade Unions and Social Structure: A Comparative Analysis," Industrial Relations, 1 (1961), pp. 75-09. "Trends in American Society," in An Outline of Man's Knowledge of the Modern World, Lyman Bryson, ed. (New York: McGraw- Hill, 1950), pp. 389-417. "The Two Party System in the I.T.U.," Labor and Nation (Fall 1950), pp. 33-45. ‘“$T" 3 ‘J'Ix $1117.