AMERICAN POLICY IN CHINA, 1899—1912: ‘A.TEST CASE FOR THE ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION OF IMPERIALISM BY Joan H. Rich A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF ARTS Department of History 1962 Professor Paul A. Varg by his sound advice and encouragement has contributed immeasurably to the writing and development of this thesis, for which I would like to express profound gratitude. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Chapter Page I. THE PROBLEM . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 II. THE CONTEMPORARY AMERICAN VIEW OF CHINA . . . 37 III. AMERICA'S ECONOMIC STAKE IN CHINA . . . . . . 64 IV. JOHN HAY AND THE FAR.EAST . . . . . . . . . . S4 V. THEODORE ROOSEVELT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128 VI. TAFT, THE BANKERS AND CHINA . . . . . . . . . 167 CONCLUSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 212 BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217 iii ABSTRACT AMERICAN POLICY IN CHINA, 1899-1912: A TEST CASE FOR THE ECONOMIC INTERPRETATION OF IMPERIALISM by Joan H. Rich The view that imperialism is caused by the economic pressures that develop in the capitalist system when it reaches the stage of monopoly and that financial interests are the controlling power behind expansion was first expressed by J. A. Hobson in his book Imperialism: A Study. To maintain a balanced economy, Hobson believed, a capitalist nation needed to export surplus goods or surplus capital. Nikolai Lenin, in his Imperialism, went even further than Hobson by maintaining that imperialism was an inevitable development of capitalism and could not be prevented by reforms in the capitalist system. This economic interpretation of imperialism has found many adherents among historians, and a number of books have been written to apply the theory to historical events. America entered an age of expansion at the end of the nineteenth century, and, in the View of these historians, her policy in the Far East offered much evidence to support the economic interpretation of imperialism. A closer lodk Joan H. Rich at this evidence shows that the formation of American policy had far more complex origins. America's interest in China was in part the outcome of an ideology that paid little attention to economic benefits. Many Americans saw the world in terms of a number of competing civilizations of which only the fittest would survive. American democracy and Anglo-Saxon civilization were at stake in China as the civilizations of the East and the West were brought into closer contact by the new means of communication. Questions of national prestige and military strategy were also involved. As a result of this outlook American statesmen came to regard the maintenance of the integrity of China and a balance of power in the Far East as vital to America's national interest. At the time America became interested in China she in fact had few investments in China and little surplus capital to invest there. Her trade with China, with the exception of manufactured cotton goods, was of minor importance. /The open door policy was inaugurated in the belief that America could act in her own self-interest to gain economic benefits at the same time that she worked for the llong range goal of upholding the territorial and administrative . “fi—N«~'-‘s int C011 of bu of th it he ‘u in Joan H. Rich integrity of China. It was assumed that there was nothing in- compatible in the two aims. During Theodore Roosevelt's term in office the problem of Japanese relations temporarily eclipsed the effort to support China against the encroachments of other powers, and Roosevelt was reluctant to assume any political commitments that America could not or would not defend. The open door policy was revised by his successor to include the concept of equality for financial investment, but the purpose remained the same-~to uphold the integrity of China. This revival of concern about China was the result of the efforts of European nations to gain concessions for railway loans to China and the increasing weakness of the Chinese government. The Taft administration also believed that it could help American business at the same time that it strengthened China against encroachment. In these early years as a world power, America still had much to learn about the importance of power in world affairs, and still had not precisely defined her national interests. The country was not yet ready to support political alliances or military adventures abroad. States- :men tried to play a power game with only economic weapons and in the end these proved to be ineffective. CHAPTER I THE PROBLEM The term "imperialism" has no precise definition, and yet it is a term freely used in almost every discussion of contemporary international relations. Historians likewise apply the term to a whole range of phenomena ranging from territorial expansion to foreign investments and to efforts to promote trade. This lack of precise meaning makes the term a poor tool of communication, but the emotional conno— tation now associated with it renders it even more unsatis- factory. Marxists and many non-Marxists equate the word with a sinister drive to dominate other peoples and assume that this desire for domination is the product of economic forces. This definition of the term "imperialism" began with the publication of J. A. HObson's highly influential .Imperialism: A Study,1 published in 1902, and received further impetus in 1916 with the publication of Nikolai Lenin's Imperialism,2 which drew heavily on Hobson, and studies by Rudolf Hilferding, Karl Kautsky and other neo—marxists. lLondOn. 1948 0 2New York, 1939. All these studies were efforts to explain the unprecedented expansion by the European Powers that took place at the end of the nineteenth century. Both Hobson and Lenin saw a qualitative difference between the aggression of the late nineteenth century and earlier expansion. Hobson made the distinction between colonialism, the settlement in new areas of people of the mother country (such as the American colonies), and imperialism, the effort to absorb a distant territory of reluctant and unassimilable people. Colonialism, he said, could be an extension of nationalism, whereas imperialism was a perversion of it and defeated any movement toward internationalism. Hobson noted that the nineteenth century differed from earlier periods in that imperialism had become a conscious policy of government, and that the world was divided among a number of competing empires. Lenin also found the nineteenth century imperialism essentially different from previous imperialism, although he did not make clear the distinction between colonialism and imperialism as did Hobson. He called imperialism an 3Hobson, pp. 6—11, 8, 19. These differences were also noted by Paul S. Reinsch, World Politics at the End of the Nineteenth Century as Influenced by the Oriental Situation (New York, London, 1925), pp. 13, 61-67. See below, Chapter II. expression of a certain phase of capitalism that was dis- tinguished by the dominance of monopoly and finance capital. It was a transition from colonialism, whereas previous aggression, which he also called imperialism, was the result of free enterprise capitalism. Disagreeing with Hobson and Kautsky, he insisted that imperialism was a necessary expression of the capitalist system, not a conscious policy of government. On the whole Lenin was not very precise in his definition of imperialism. Hobson's analysis of imperialism was based almost entirely on the history of the British Empire. He wanted to prove that Britain's deliberate policy of expansion adopted in the 1890's was financially ruinous to the country, undermined her domestic institutions, and threatened to involve her in war. He sought to find the reason she continued such a disastrous policy, for he assumed that governments always acted on some rational principle. As Hebson saw it, the answer lay in the fact that while the policy was disastrous to the country as a whole, it was exceedingly profitable to a powerful minority who were able to bring decisive influence to bear on government policy. 4Lenin, pp. 76, 88, 90-95; E. M. Winslow, The Pattern of Imperialism (New York, 1948), pp. 183-88. He explored the usual reasons given for imperialist policy and found them wanting. He proved that the areas annexed by Britain after 1870 were not profitable centers of trade because little trade was gained that Britain would not have had in any case; and that the trade of these areas was a very small proportion of the total trade of the nation, although the colonies might furnish a few critical imports unobtainable in other regions. For the nation as a whole colonies were uneconomical because the expense of running them ate up any profits they might provide. Trade was therefore not the principal reason for acquiring colonies.5 Hobson also rejected the theory that colonies were acquired for philanthropic reasons, to spread the benefits of British government and civilization, because as he pointed out, Britain's colonies were ruled autocratically from London.6 Finally he pointed out that these new territories were not needed as outlets for excess population because most of them had climates unfit for European settlers and ‘were already well populated by natives. In any case, Britain 5Hobson, pp. 28-40. 6Hobson, pp. 26, 113-24. was not overpopulated.7 But if Britain herself did not profit from overseas expansion, there were powerful vested interests in the country that did profit greatly from colonial trade and the new opportunities colonies provided. In the matter of trade, there were some industries that found a greater margin of profit in selling overseas than in the home market even though the home market might have absorbed a larger volume of goods. Among the industries that profited were the arms industries, tools, textiles, hardware, those supplying railway equipment and other public works. All of these were large, organized industries apt to be influential with government. Among the individuals who profited were those who had jobs at stake in the new countries, civil servants, teachers, engineers, missionaries, in other words men who had not the same outlet for their talents at home. It was again significant that those men who had a vested interest in colonial jobs tended to be men who had close ties in government circles. Finally the military had a 7H0bson, pp. 27, 42—43. 8Hobson, pp. 46-51. vested interest in expansion. None of these vested interests, however, might have been decisive in formulating policy if it were not for the changes going on in the economy which tended to concentrate great power in a few hands. Hobson drew attention to the great trusts and monopolies that had developed as protection against the cut— throat competition of free enterprise in a rapidly expanding economy. The trusts put great wealth in the hands of a few men, and since the wealthy could not spend all their money on consumption, they were forced to save most of it. These savings could not be profitably invested in the domestic economy under the condition of trusts. The surplus savings could therefore be used either to produce more than the domestic economy would absorb but which could be marketed overseas as "surplus goods,’ or the savings themselves could be invested abroad as “surplus capital." In either form, it was the excessive saving that created a disequilibrium in the domestic economy and forced attention abroad. It was the profitableness of overseas investment that was the moving force behind imperialism. HObson found support for this theory in the figures that showed that, whereas trade as a whole did not grow significantly within the British Empire as new lands were acquired, there was a large and 7 significant increase in overseas financial investment, which yielded far greater profit than domestic investment.9 According to Hebson, all American economists agreed that the United States was overproducing, and this belief 'was widely reflected among publicists, statesmen and business— men of the period.10 Since, as Hebson pointed out, all the European nations were reaching the point of overproduction, the competition for overseas markets and outlets for investment was growing increasingly intense. Hobson was the first to define the role of finance capital in imperialist expansion. The financiers, as the dealers in investment, were the principal advocates of imperialism. The individual investors, even the heads of large trusts, were the "catspaws" of these men. United by the strongest bonds of organization, always in closest and quickest touch with one another, situated in the very heart of the business capital of every State, controlled, so far as Europe is concerned, chiefly by men of a single and peculiar race, who have behind them many centuries of financial experience, they are in a unique position to manipulate the policy of nations.11 9Hobson, pp. 73-88, 52-56. OHobson, p. 76; Brooks Adams, America's Economic Supremacy (New York, 1947). PP. 71, 79, passim; Charles S. Campbell, Jr., Special Business Interests and the Open Door Policy (New Haven, 1951), pp. 1-4. llHobson, pp. 56—57. Hobson noted that once investments had been made abroad, the government often stepped in to protect the investment; outright territorial acquisition often followed political intervention. In this way government took over the risk of private investment but the profit stayed in private hands. The nation did not benefit, but the influential few did. Even worse than this manipulation of government support for private gain was the financier's use of stocks and bonds, not as sources of income in themselves, but as means for speculation in the international money market.12 In this way the whole economy of Britain became tied up with foreign investment through the manipulation of private financiers. Hobson differed from Lenin primarily in believing that imperialism was not an inevitable development from capitalism. If the capital accumulation, instead of going into enforced saving, were more widely distributed in higher wages or taxes to the community, he argued, it could find release in consumption rather than in overseas investment; and if competition were kept free and trade barriers lowered, lower prices would induce a wider domestic market. Social 12Hobson, pp. 56-61. reform was therefore the necessary corrective to imperialism. Hobson explained the ways in which imperialists impeded these reforms at home, and how the administration of the empire congested the machinery of government and further impeded reform.l4 Hobson believed that any reasons for advocating imperialism other than the economic were ideological fronts for the financiers' search for gain. He analysed and disposed of all the contemporary defenses of imperialist policy. His lengthy attack on the Social Darwinist explan- ation of national rivalry and imperialism was particularly significant because it suggests that it was a widely held view Which was with many people perfectly sincere, although in Hobson's opinion completely illogical.15 Hobson was ready to concede that there were some people who were genuinely concerned to ”do good,9 to bring western civili- zation, religion or education to badkward people, but he felt that many of these were unconscious hypocrites, and -others the tools of business interests who played on l3Hobson, pp. 81-93. 14Hobson, pp. 125—52. 15Hobson, pp. 153-95; William L. Langer, The Diplomacy of Imperialism (New York, 1951), pp. 88-94. 10 philanthropic impulses. ’Vague, well—meaning phrases had become the cloak for deliberate exploitation of backward areas.’ The imperialists also played on the deeper instinctive fears and impulses of their compatriots, such as the desire for land, fear of other races, nationalism and pure aggressive- ness. Hobson thus relegated to a secondary role a number of explanations for imperialism.Which later theorists have regarded as primary. The Marxists too have tended to regard all other theories as intellectual camouflage for materialist interests.16 After reviewing England's relations with some of the native populations of her Empire, Hobson turned to the question of China, which he, in company with many of his contemporaries, saw as the last great open market and field of international rivalry. He felt that China would be too large a bite for the powers to swallow, and that cooperation between financial interests of the imperialist countries was a more likely development than conflict. This seemed indeed to forecast Ithe international consortium of a few years later. .Hobson had this to say about American policy: ”The United States, whose interest in China for investment and for trade is developing faster than that of any European Power, will l6Hobson, pp. 197-222; Lenin, p. 84; Winslow, pp. 223-36. 11 certainly insist upon an open door and will soon be in a position to back her claim by strong naval power."l7 Hobson was greatly concerned about the possible breakup of China and the loss of her valuable civilization, and like many other commentators hoped for a judicious interchange of cultural values. Hobson allowed greater scope than Lenin did for the interplay of economic and non-economic forces in international affairs. He was also more hopeful that domestic reform would lead to a more equitable distribution of income and that international reform to establish some sort of referee in the relations of the civilized and backward nations would put an end to the aggressive tendencies of the day. He put the major blame for deliberate imperialism on the inter- national businessman, financier and speculator, and on the prevalent assumption that a government must protect the interests of any individual citizen regardless of the over- all national interest.18 This was a point widely taken up by historians who adopted the "economic interpretation." In Lenin's view, imperialism was the inevitable out— ' come of the capitalist system, it was the last stage of l7Hobson, p. 310. 18Hobson, pp. 41-42, 228-37, 356-60. 12 capitalism. Following Marx's line of reasoning, he maintained that the development of trusts and monopolies was the inevitable result of a free enterprise economy, and he cited evidence to prove that the stage of monopoly capital had been reached by 1916. Monopoly had also extended into the banking industry, and this was a fundamental step in the transformation of capitalism into capitalist imperialism. The banks ran the industrial world, and since their largest profit came from floating new companies, speculation and manipulation of the money market, their control penetrated every sphere of public life, regardless of the form of government. A central elite drawn from government, industry and banking ruled each capitalist country. Just as this elite had evolved in each nation, a few powerful capitalist nations had arisen to dominate the world.19 By a line of reasoning similar to Hobson's, Lenin maintained that surplus capital had to seek outlets abroad. ”but to him this was inevitable. VAs long as capitalism .remains what it is, surplus capital will never be utilized for the purpose of raising the standard of living of the masses in a given country, for this would mean a decline in 19Lenin, pp. 20, 31, 53-59, passim. 13 profits for the capitalists."20 The export of capital re- placed the export of goods, and financial capital gradually spread over the whole world. This development was dominated by the powerful nations. "As the export of capital increased, and as the foreign and colonial relations and the 'spheres of influence' of the big monopolist combines expanded, things 'naturally' gravitated towards an international agreement among these combines, and toward the formation of international cartels," Lenin argued.21 However, he saw no hope, as Kautsky had done, that such international agreements would replace the competition and bring peace. They were merely a change in the form of the struggle. The financiers would always seek control of the markets for surplus goods and surplus capital and of their sources of raw material as the best way to defeat their rivals in other nations.22 Since loans abroad were usually tied to some form of concession, these loans involved political considerations and brought an intensification of colonial expansion. Political division of the world therefore inevitably followed 20Lenin, p. 63. 21Lenin, p. 68. 22Lenin, p. 83. 14 the economic division by the cartels.23 According to Lenin the economic forces were inexorable. He assumed that men always acted according to the profit motive. Thus it followed that "the capitalists divide up the world, not out of any particular malice but because the degree of concentration which has been reached forces them to adopt this method in order to get profits."24 Monopoly was an inevitable outgrowth of free enterprise, and imperialism the inevitable outgrowth of monopoly. Capital had to seek outlets abroad because it could not be utilized in the domestic market without loss of profit. This infallible rule meant that no reforms seeking a return to free competition and free trade could permanently reverse the trend. By placing exclusive emphasis on the inevitability of economic forces Lenin's theory is far less subtle than Hobson's, which found room for non-economic forces in the total scheme of imperialism. The simplicity of his scheme may partly explain why Lenin's views became established as communist dogma, and reinforced the tendency among historians to regard economic causes as basic to history, although one finds fewer echoes of his specific arguments than those of Hobson in the works of American historians. 23Lenin, pp. 89-90. 24Lenin, p. 75. 15 Whatever the merits of Lenin's theory as a description of internal economic development, the essential point for the study of foreign policy was the assumption that capital must be exported; that a nation's policy was determined by the necessity for acquiring outlets for this surplus capital: and that political aggression followed economic aggression. Historians have applied the economic theories of Hobson, Lenin and others to their accounts of political events, and it became fashionable to regard the holocaust of the First World War as the folly of imperialists and financiers.25 The whole aggressive movement of the great powers from the 18808 on was regarded as part of the inevitable development of the capitalist system, with the international rivalries leading inevitably to war. American policy in China was regarded as a facet of this world-wide imperialist tendency. A look at several of these historians who accepted the economic interpretation, shows the shortcomings of .applying a theory to the facts rather than deriving the 26 theory from the facts. For example, Parker T. Moon followed fairly closely Hobson's description of the 25Winslow, p. 45. 26Imperialism and world Politics (New York, 1927). l6 imperialist impulses in Great Britain beginning in the 18805. As other nations began to catch up to British industrial development, she no longer held the lead in world markets and surpluses began to develop at home, particularly in the key iron and cotton industries. The creation of surpluses was the "inevitable result of the economic laws governing capitalist production."27 Since capital could no longer be invested in these industries, it began to look for outlets abroad. At the same time the increase of industrialization required more and more raw materials, and the growing opulence of Britain created a demand for tropical luxuries. These were the accepted reasons for needing colonies. Moon likewise gave great weight to the ideal of national economic self- sufficiency as a motivating factor in imperialism. Each nation wanted to control as much as possible the supply of raw materials for its own economy. It was not the capitalist class as a whole, Moon believed, that was interested in imperialism, but only a minority. This minority included many influential individuals and was dominated by financial interests. It was supported by such vested interests as the shipping magnates, the arms 27Moon, p. 30. 28Moon, pp. 25-34. 17 industry, the army and navy, segments of the civil service, missionaries; and publicists played on a variety of ideas and emotions to gain popular support.29 Moon did not acknow- ledge his debt to Hobson for these categories or for his general theory, which is perhaps an indication of how widely prevalent Hobson's interpretation had become. Moon's arguments against imperialism in his conclusion also reflected Hobson's arguments. Moon discussed briefly the development of imperialist policy in the European nations, but did not devote a section to tracing the transformation of American policy to imperial— ism or spelling out the economic impetus behind American expansion. He believed that the American expansion across the continent was not imperialist, but stated that the expansionist movement at the end of the century had the same causes as English imperialism. The theory enabled Moon to reduce the tumultuous decades prior to 1914 to an orderly and easily understood drama in which the villain was finance capitalism. In his brief history of China from 1894 to 1918 he stated that {imperialism" did not begin until after 1894 when the 29Moon, pp. 58-74. 30Moon, pp. 412-13. 18 battle for concessions began. The earlier "commercialism" often used force but was not a war of conquest. It aimed at the open door which was the opposite of imperialism. "But the opening of the Far East led inevitably to a desire for monopoly of markets, mines, and railway building, hence for monopolistic 'spheres of influence', and also for naval bases and in some cases, territory."31’ The control of the railways, he believed, was the crucial point at issue in China. For example, the Chinese Eastern Railway, "nominally a private industrial project . . . was really an imperialist move on the part of the Russian Government. The railway was first and foremost a strategic railway to advance Russian imperialist interests in the Far East,"32 Railroad negotiations were a complex mixture of business and politics, but ”in most cases the primary factor was the desire of a group of capitalists to obtain the diplomatic backing of its own government in order to secure profitable contracts and to ward off competitors,"33 He went on: But the banking concerns competing for Chinese Railway contracts were less interested in the 31Moon, p. 321. 32Moon, p. 333. 33Moon, p. 339. 19 economic welfare of the whole country and ultimate profitability of the railway system than in the immediate advantage of obtaining for themselves big concessions by enlisting diplomatic aid. And the diplomats readily joined hands with the bankers and made the gaining of a concession as Lord Salisbury said, not a pure industrial proposition but a ”political matter."34 In accordance with his theory, Moon considered American policy in China largely in economic terms. IThe Open Door Notes were designed to help American commerce, 35’ "which had grown to large proportions." He did not explain precisely what moved John Hay to act in support of this commerce or what the particular trade interests in China were. Since Hay overlooked the vitally important role of investment in the struggle in China, later administrations tried to make good this error. Moon did not see any difference between America's role in the Boxer negotiations and that of the other powers. He considered Theodore Roosevelt's policy one of consenting to Japanese aggrandizement in Korea in exchange for the safety of the Philippines.36 Moon is unclear in his interpretation of the Knox Neutralization Proposal and the creation of the banking syndicate. 0n the one hand he says that Knox "seized upon? 34Moon, p. 340. 35Moon, p. 341. 36Moon, p. 347. 20 the Harriman plan for the Chinchow-Aigun railway to put forth his proposal, suggesting Knox's motive was political. On the other hand he said the bankers' syndicate was "defeated" in Manchuria, indicating the purpose was after all financial. The general implication of the section was that because bankers were involved in lending money to China, the motives were sinister.37 However, when Wilson wanted to re-establish the consortium in 1918, it was because he saw this as "the best way to prevent China from becoming, through Japanese loans, a Japanese protectorate."38 Moon regarded the international consortium as the best method of providing capital to backward nations without endangering peace.39 Moon's analysis of events tended to follow his theory, but his imprecision in the use of the term "imperialism” and occasional vagueness of interpretation left room for doubt that the theory applied in all cases. With his emphasis so strongly on economic factors, he tended to disregard contributing factors. In his discussion of China he believed the role of the railroad financiers in the development of spheres of influence was crucial, and neglected the problems 37Moon, pp. 366-70. 38Moon, p. 371. 39Moon, p. 536. 21 attendant on the rivalries between the European powers. Nor did he give any evidence that the statesmen acted under pressure from financial interests or that helping these interests was the primary aim of the statesmen themselves. This was merely assumed on circumstantial evidence. What is the link between the theory of economic necessity and the creation of policy by individual statesmen? It is precisely this policy-making end of the question of economic determinism that concerned Charles A. Beard in his bodk, The Idea of National Interest.40 Beard saw the answer in terms that were essentially psychological. Members of a political party reflected the views of their supporters. ”Moreover private citizens entering the service of government do not pass through a personal metamorphasis . . . . They are bound to bring with them the thoughts, practices and sympathies of the group in which they have moved in a private capacity."41 Government acted through the agency of indi- vidual men, who were prominent either in or out of government service before they received high posts. In these circumstances advice given, demands made, policies formed and choices of action made. by or under the influence of men ”of affairs and position" 40New York, 1934. 41Beard, The:§dea, pp. 116-17. 22 moving in the same environment and associated by ties of friendship, favor, family, clans and business relationship, are bound to conform to a recognizable frame which displays, above all minor deflections, a consistent unity, a set of definite characteristics and an unmistakable bias which is naturally representative and favorable to the group from which these men, giving the advice, voicing the demands and making the decisions have come. Add to it the fact that the whole operates within a profit economy characterized by intense competition for advantage, for raw materials and for markets, and for legislation, administration and domestic and foreign actions of public bodies favorable to such an economy; that men are scarcely actuated in their practical, private affairs by any other philosophy of public welfare or private advancement than that implied by such an economy; and there is but little question that a distinct pattern of social, political and economic thought and action is bound to emerge.42 While true up to a point, this theory assumed a logic and consistency in men's thinking which did not always in fact exist; and that a man's outlook in one sphere of activity would transfer without any essential change to another. Thus Beard assumed that men would not learn from or change in a new situation. With this psychological link to business interests as the key to the actions of statesmen, Beard traced the domination of the interests and ideas of big business on American policy from the 18805 to 1932, when the book was 42Beard, The Idea, p. 118. 23 written. In this period some victories went to the rival agrarian interests so that American policy was not entirely consistent. The antagonism of business and agriculture went badk to Hamilton and Jefferson, Beard maintained, but by the turn of the century business was in the ascendant. It needed new markets for its surplus goods and outlets for its surplus capital, and it turned more and more to the government for help in finding markets. Government obliged by becoming more and more concerned with helping business abroad. Beard regarded this as the basis of the open door policy.43 Beard, like Hobson, regarded the practice of pro- tecting nationals abroad in whatever enterprise they under— took as a dangerous and ill—considered policy. Although he admitted that government did sometimes discriminate between the enterprises it considered to be in the ”national interest” and those that were not, he believed that national interest was wrongly conceived by American statesmen as either a sum of particular tangible interests, or a balance of such interests in society.44 Yet, he pointed out, the Senate investigation of Philippine independence showed that 43Beard, The Idea, Chaps. III to V. 44Beard, The Idea, pp. 110, 462, 21-9, 39. 24 no one ever really bothered to work out the balance sheet of what the national interest really was. Beard made a careful survey of the bureaucratic apparatus of government and its connections with the economic interests.46 He laid special stress on the role of the Navy as an early harbinger of imperialism and the ideological influence of Captain Alfred T. Mahan, who was one of his major villains. He misread Mahan in regarding him as primarily concerned with economic interests, for Mahan was really concerned with sea power for its own sake, and with wider ideological matters which Beard regarded as window dressing.47 Beard gave a long statistical analysis of America's stake abroad and the pressures of the domestic market to prove that American policy was directed to finding markets for surplus goods. Yet one fact seems to contradict all his theories. Although the domestic market was supposed to be saturated at the turn of the century, the fact is that it grew as rapidly as the foreign market during the period after 1900. Of the total production of exportable goods, a 45Beard, The Idea, pp. 513-29. 46Beard, The Idea, pp. 408-62. 47Beard, The Idea, pp. 53—64, 337—40, 429-42; see also Charles A. Beard, A Foreign Policy for America (New York, London, 1940), pp. 39—48. 25 fairly steady ten percent was exported; the proportion of exports did not rise. And while about the year 1876 America began to export more than she imported, the relation of the excess of exports over imports to the total exports did not change, but remained at roughly ten percent of the total trade activity.48 Thus our exports grew only with the growth of the whole domestic economy and presumably with the growth of the world economy in general. Although only about ten percent of American produce was exported, a seemingly small percent of the total economy, Beard pointed out that this could be the difference between depression and prosperity, and moreover in certain crucial industries the percentage of exports was much greater than the average. In the era after the First World War, for instance, we exported about half our cotton, turpentine, resin; a third of our agricultural machinery and sewing machines, and a high proportion of our petroleum.49 But surely the whole concept of trade is that each nation produces more of what it produces best to pay for those goods it cannot produce? Beard, writing in the early months of the New Deal, 48Beard, The Idea, pp. 245—46, 247-48. 49Beard, The Idea, pp. 256-64. 26 felt there was hope that the whole fallacy of our foreign policy would be corrected. He saw signs that the government ‘would concentrate on building a domestic market so that there would no longer be pressure for overseas markets for goods and capital, and that our foreign policy could be restricted to really legitimate interests. According to Beard, President Roosevelt's conception is one that fixes clearly the center of gravity for American policy in the United States itself, envisages the possibility of a more intense exploitation of American resources, contemplates a more equitable distribution of real wealth within the country, and accepts with reluctance and care only the minimum of international action which life under modern conditions impels.50 With his assumption that the only thing that embroiled a nation in foreign difficulties was the pressure for markets, Beard became essentially an advocate of isolation in the 19305. The limitations of the assumption became evident with the rise of Nazi Germany, the Japanese attack on Pearl Harbor and other events that led to World War II. These events also suggested that there might have been other motives behind the policies that are called imperialistic. A bodk Which applied the theoretical views of Hobson and Lenin specifically to the United States and its foreign 50Beard, The Idea, p. 544. 27 expansion was Dollar Diplomacy; A Study in American Imperialism by Scott Nearing and Joseph Freeman.51 These authors believed that America's imperialist expansion was the inevitable outcome of her capitalist system, and allowed far less scope to non-economic forces than did either Moon or Beard. "Economic necessity," they stated, "dictates that every modern industrial society must develop foreign markets for its surplus products; must control sources of food, fuel, minerals, timber and other raw materials; must secure business opportunities for the investment of surplus capital."52 They contended that imperialism ”is not peculiar to any nation but corresponds to a certain stage in the development of economic surplus."53 (According to the theory accepted by Freeman and Nearing, the search for outlets for surplus capital was behind American policy in China,’and the authors imply as much in their discussion of the case of the American China Development Corporation, the Harriman-Straight railway plans and the loan negotiations of the Taft administration. The consortium was in their view the beginning of the era of 51New York, 1927. 2 . ... Nearing and Freeman, p. x111. 3 . Nearing and Freeman, p. xv. 28 international financial trusts. America's whole policy was aimed at creating a financial control, particularly in Manchuria. This interpretation is based on the assumption that if a J. P. Morgan or Standard Oil or Harriman were involved, a transaction must be aimed at such control.54 Yet the authors offer no decisive evidence that financial control was the primary consideration of the State Department. They quote Taft's message to Congress saying that our investment in China is "to enable that country to help itself" and to help "the promotion of those essential reforms to which China is pledged by treaties,"55 as a proof that American diplomacy was concerned with the export of capital, but they give no reason for their interpretation. Moreover the figures cited by Nearing and Freeman indicate what a small amount of American capital actually was involved in China, and they confess that before 1900 America was not a great exporter of capital "as the domestic demand for capital more than covered the available amount of - n5 - investment surplus. 6 It was not until after World War I that America became a creditor nation and the need to export 54Nearing and Freeman, pp. 37, 40—51. 5Nearing and Freeman, p. 265. 6 . Nearing and Freeman, p. l. 29 capital became crucial. The implication is that the 19205 were the real age of American imperialism. But if the export of capital were not of crucial importance before the First World War, then the theory of Nearing and Freeman would seem to indicate that the search for raw materials or for a market for surplus goods was the main motive of American imperialism. Since the authors give no evidence of the crucial importance of any Chinese imports to America, presumably they believed that search for markets was the main consideration. Like Moon and many other commen- tators they interpreted the Open Door Notes in this way. IThe open door policy was designed to protect American business interests in China and America's "sphere of influence" in Manchuria.I They defined a "sphere of influence” as territory where a nation will permit no other to exert political influence and where it will lead in the exploitation of natural resources; but they did not specify how America wielded such power or what interests were involved at the turn of the century. They also asserted that the claim based on the concession of American China Development Corporation served as a precedent for claims to the exploitation of Manchuria. 7Nearing and Freeman, pp. 11—12. 58Nearing and Freeman, pp. 35-38, 258. 30 The account of events in China in Dollar Diplomacy was almost exclusively concerned with economic developments. It omitted all reference to the policy of Theodore Roosevelt's administration, but dealt at relative length with the loan negotiations in which "the State Department has actively cooperated with American bankers to obtain concessions both in the Near East and the Far East."59 In the books by Moon and by Nearing and Freeman, certain assumptions were made about the economic nature of imperialism based on theories similar to those of Hobson and Lenin. In the case of China both books gave a fairly factual account of events, though with stress on economic events, without making any careful link between these events and the theory. The reader is left to believe that they have proved their case. In both instances the authors began with the theory and applied it to the facts rather than beginning with the facts to arrive at the theory. In neither book was there any effort to document the essential link between economic conditions and political action. Just how was the necessary imperialist policy evolved? Who put what pressures on the statesmen? What alternatives were considered? What analysis determined that diplomatic pressures should 9Nearing and Freeman, p. 259. 31 be applied to introduce capital into China at the possible expense of outlets in Japan or Siberia? What were the parti— cular problems involved in introducing capital into China? A foreign policy is not self-created out of air. It is put into effect by individual statesmen after much discussion and planning, so that if the export of capital were the primary aim of the American State Department, one would expect there to be some documentary evidence of the fact. Beard tried to supply the missing gap between the theory and the events with a psychological theory, but again did not apply his theory to the individual case. Before turning to a study of the facts about American policy in China to see whether they accord with the theory, it might be pertinent to make a number of general criticisms concerning the application of these economic theories of imperialism to history. E. M. Winslow has written a very useful history and critique of the economic interpretation of imperialism, The Pattern of Imperialism, in which he is particularly caustic about the historical use of these theories: The economic interpretation of imperialism and war has one great advantage over other interpretations, and thereon doubtless depends its great popularity: it gives people something concrete and apparently simple to talk about. Whatever the cause of war may be, one of the major causes of the economic interpretation 32 is the ease with which it can be invdked. It appeals to the logical and scientific mind in an age that places great store on economic values and science. It deals with concrete factors and material forces which people feel they can understand. Above all, it carries an air of sophistication which can be imparted with great educational facility. By an easy transference to personal motives and experiences, it enables the man in the street to see the world as himself writ large.60 The historians who have accepted the economic inter- pretation, Winslow felt, usually did not worry about the fine points of the theories of Hobson, Lenin and the other economists. They tended to accept the assumption that, at least in political life, the basic drive of man is the search for profit; that modern industry produces more goods than can be used in the home markets and more capital than can be absorbed, so that imperialism, economic rivalry and war are the result. They have not, for instance, considered whether imperialism is a matter of policy or Whether it is inevitable. He points out that to the economic historian imperialism is always the same, and it is always a bad thing. Moreover it is usually attributed to capitalism for one reason or another. The analysis is often accompanied by a message for the amelioration of the situation through such measures as international mandates, international 6OWinslow, p. 44. 33 government or socialism. The whole question of imperialism thus becomes loaded with emotional overtones.61 Writers on imperialism have usually proved conclusively that imperialism did not pay the mother country, and they have generally accepted Hobson's View that the government is the tool of special interests instead of raising the question whether there might be other motives of a strategic or political nature for acquiring colonies. There is sometimes a tendency to regard states as persons rather than as institutions run by individual men, and something like a concept of the "economic state" replaces the "economic man” as the unit of discussion. It is assumed that nations, like men, always make rational decisions on the basis of economic choice, whereas nations, like men, are often irrational.6 In addition to these assumptions about the nature of imperialism, there has been considerable looseness in the use of the term "economic,' as Winslow also points out. Hobson and others have shown that certain colonies have not paid economically, but they still maintain that the misguided belief in the profitability of colonies was the basic motive 61Winslow. pp. 42-46 . 62Winslow, pp. 51—60, 91. 34 for their acquisition. This explanation, however, does not prove economic causality but only defines an ideology. With a different set of beliefs but with the same economic system the colony might not be acquired.6 Many transactions dealing in money or material goods are not "economic" at all, Winslow shows, but result from value judgments. For instance, a nation that goes to war to acquire raw materials has made a judgment against buying the materials in the open market or other alternatives that might be open to it. The price people are ready to pay for profit is a value judgment that will vary with the intensity of the desire and with a wide variety of other values in a society.64 In addition economic developments are often the result of other motives. The development of monopolies may not be primarily an economic matter but the attempt of businessmen to find security in an insecure world. On the international scene, imperialism can be seen as a similar search for security. Fear or rivalry, not profit, might be considered the basic motive.65 63Hobson, pp. 71-73; Winslow, pp. 56—60, 216—26. 64Winslow, pp. 216-26. 65Winslow, pp. 201-06. 35 A wide range of decisions often considered economic are really political, including regulations for the control of an economic system, or a change in the economic system.66 The economic theory of history makes many far- reaching assumptions about the nature of man that are never really supported by an accompanying psychological explanation. This theory never proves that man is in fact fundamentally motivated by the search for profit, nor that even if he were that this is necessarily an evil. According to Winslow, ”historians have generally found it easy to believe that economic motives are purely one sided expressions of human selfishness and that economic competition . . . is exclusive and non-reciprocal."67 Winslow suggests on the contrary that trade and economic activity in general can be of mutual benefit. The psychological assumption of Hobson and Lenin that other motives for imperialism, such as the desire to do good, are but the hypocritical covers for a desire for gain, is slippery ground for an historian. It is very difficult to prove that a man who says he undertakes a policy because he wants to bring civilization to the natives 66Winslow, p. 193. 67Winslow, p. 44. 36 really means he wants to lend them money to fill his own pockets. This difficulty arises even when one examines actions as opposed to words. Is the missionary sincere or the tool of finance? Why does the banker lend money to a corrupt regime? Is a president looking for votes or for his place in history in championing the spread of civili- zation? Both the cynical and the naive approach can be equally biased. All these criticisms suggest that there is far more complexity in the motives of men and of nations than the economic theory will allow, even in the hands of such a subtle theorist as Hobson. When one turns to look at the events, this complexity of motive is confirmed. CHAPTER II THE CONTEMPORARY AMERICAN VIEW OF CHINA The problem of China loomed large in a number of boOks at the turn of the century by writers who wielded considerable influence on government policy. A study of works by Captain A. T. Mahan, Brooks Adams, Henry Adams, even the anti-imperialist Paul S. Reinsch, and the American correspondence of the English diplomat, Sir Cecil Spring Rice give an indication of the context of American thinking. Although the desire for markets was one reason for the interest in China, the economic motive was by no means predominant. It has not always been the case in America that policy was influenced by intellectuals, but in this period American intellectuals carried special weight because they happened to be close friends of the men who made policy. Henry Adams was the most intimate companion of John Hay over a long period of years. His brother, Brooks, and Mahan were part of the circle that included Theodore Roosevelt, Henry Cabot Lodge, William W. Rookhill and Sir Cecil Spring’ Rice. While it is of course untrue to say that Roosevelt, Hay or Rockhill believed everything that Mahan or the Adams 37 38 brothers wrote, and Paul Reinsch was not of the circle, their ideas are indicative of the general views of the world that were exchanged over the dinner table and in letters, and many specific ideas of the intellectuals appear in the writings of the statesmen, particularly of Roosevelt, who was a widely read man. These books indicate that contemporary thought was far more influenced by Social Darwinism than by Marxism. Indeed the impact of Darwinism on all aspects of intellectual life in America has often been noted.1 With a basis in true science, Darwinian principles were carried over into social and political life to form the basis of a number of pseudo- scientific theories. In its attempt to be scientific and in its stress on inevitable conflict, Darwinism.had much in common with Marxism. Moreover they both could become an all-embracing system for the explanation of just about everything. In the present day whensSocial Darwinism has lost much of its appeal, it is harder to realize the hold it had on the minds of men of an earlier generation. Applied to the affairs of men, Darwinism could cut in many directions, and it was a more nebulous concept than lRichard Hofstadter, Social Darwinism in American Thought, 1860-1915 (Philadelphia, 1944). 39 Marxism. In America it was first used by conservatives to defend the status quo, later by radicals as a reason to change society. That it was constantly cited as a reason for imperialist action is substantiated by the fact that Hobson undertook a careful refutation of Darwinist theory.2 Despite the fallacies Hobson pointed out, echoes of Social Darwinism appear constantly in American discussions of world affairs at the turn of the century, and China was often seen as the final battleground between Western and Eastern societies. The influence of Social Darwinism is very apparent in Brooks Adams' book, America's Economic Supremacy,3 a group of related essays that appeared in 1900. In close to hysterical terms, Adams expressed the view that all western civilization was at stake in China. He maintained, in one of these grandiose historical analyses beloved of the nineteenth century, that the center of civilization had constantly moved westward and that America had assumed the mantle of leadership fallen from the shoulders of a decadent England. The Pacific would soon rival the Atlantic as a center of O l I I 4 I I O commerce and CiVilization. In a companion historical 2Hobson, pp. 153-95. 3New York, 1947. 174. 4O generalization, Adams maintained that there was a traditional rivalry between sea power and land power; that opposed to the sea power of England and America there was a rival land power centered on Russia and Germany.5 China would be the center of the struggle between these forces. Adams constantly wrote of this struggle in evolutionary terms. VAlready," he wrote, "America has been drawn into war over the dismemberment of one dying civilization [the Spanish Empire]; and it cannot escape the conflict which must be waged over the carcass of another._"6 Nations, like individuals, like species, had risen and decayed. China was in the death throes. Adams noted with some regret the symptoms of decline in the British Empire.7 Since only the fittest would survive, America had to be strong to face the impending battle with barbarian Russia. Fitness involved not only military strength but economic strength. Since "society tends to become organized in greater and denser masses,"8 America must consolidate her economic system and reorganize her administration. A 5Brooks Adams, pp. 112—19. 6Brooks Adams, p. 80. 7Brooks Adams, pp. 138—67. 8Brooks Adams, p. 84. 41 free enterprise economy was a luxury she could no longer afford. The economic forces must be controlled to the great end of saving American civilization.9 Adams was aware of the great economic stake in China. Like others, he regarded China as the last great market open for the surplus goods of an industrial society.10 But winning the China market was only a facet of the wider struggles between civilizations. ’Control of this market would strengthen America and keep Russia from this strategic location. 9‘ "‘ .4 [/'1- 7~ “ ““f Adams conveys a sense of inevitability about the process of America's exploitation of China. Civilizations either grew or they decayed. Expansion was a symptom of growth. Interim solutions, he implies, could not prevent the struggle that would ensue from this growth. The best thing that could happen for her [America] would be for China to remain quiescent. But the very success and energy of America makes it unlikely that China can stay stationary; an effort at development is inevitable, and it behooves Americans to consider whether they can safely allow that development to be wholly controlled by others.11 9Brooks Adams, pp. 99-106, 135. 10 Brooks Adams, pp. 78-79, 89. 11Brooks Adams, pp. 192-93. 42 Adams even went so far as to say that aggression was better than sitting back to wait for the impending struggle. In spite of his dire warnings that America needed to reform, Adams thought America was best fitted to survive in the twentieth century. He concluded his argument on this note: Our geographical position, our wealth and our energy pre-eminently fit us to enter upon the development of eastern Asia and to reduce it to a part of our economic system. And, moreover, the laws of nature are immutable. Money will flow where it earns most return, and investments once made are always protected. Evidently Americans cannot be excluded from China without a struggle, and they may not, perhaps, be welcomed by those who have hitherto shown most anxiety to obtain a foothold there. The Chinese question, therefore, must be accepted as the great problem of the future, as a problem from which there can be no escape; and as these great struggles for supremacy sometimes involve an appeal to force, safety lies in being armed and organized against all emergencies.12 Adams was totally unsentimental in his approach to politics. Whatever his views of England, for instance, he did not waste time in eulogies on her past glories. The business of life is a constant struggle, and power was the key to survival. Moral considerations were beside the 371 point. he felt America must expand or decay; that survival was dependent on the markets of China and the defeat of rivals, notably Russia. This survival was essential to 12BroOks Adams, p. 194. 43 preserve American civilization, which was replacing the decaying British Empire as balance wheel in world affairs.’ Captain Alfred T. Mahan, like Brooks Adams and John Hay, seemed to feel there was a cosmic tendency pushing America into world affairs. "There is a spirit abroad,” he wrote, ”which may yet challenge our claim to exclude its action and interference in any quarter unless it finds us prepared there in adequate strength to forbid it or to exercise our own." This cosmic tendency was often expressed in terms of the evolutionary struggle, for Mahan went on: Like all natural forces the impulse takes the direction of least resistance, but when in its course it comes upon some region rich in possi- bilities, but unfruitful through the incapacity or negligence of those who dwell therein, the incompetent race or system will go down, as the inferior race has ever fallen back and disappeared before the persistent impact of the superior.1 Beard, who regarded Mahan as one of the prime spokesmen for the capitalist class and the expansionist politicians, admitted that Mahan's ideas were not based on economic motives but on two basic maxims: (l) 9Self interest is not only a legitimate but a fundamental cause for national policy; one which needs no cloak of hypocricy."; and (2) ”The l3Alfred T. Mahan, The Interest of America in Sea Power Present and Future (Boston, 1897): PP. 165-66. 44 first law of states, as of men, is self—preservation—-a term which cannot be narrowed to the bare tenure of a stationary round of existence. Growth is a property of healthy life."14 Natural growth was the basic force behind expansion, and strength was necessary to maintain this growth. It was Mahan's basic belief that sea power should be the instrument for America‘s natural survival and prestige, although the reader at times feels that Mahan is in love with ships just for their own sake. In the book that propelled Mahan into the public eye in 1890, The Influence of Sea Power Upon History 1660-1783,15 he analysed the geographic, political, economic, racial and other factors that created sea power. Naval power and the power of the merchant fleet would reinforce each other. In some places Mahan talked of building a merchant fleet as a reserve military force; and in others of building a fleet to protect commerce, an enter- prise in which men had engaged since ancient times. Although he realized America had few merchant ships to defend, he maintained she needed a navy to protect her coast l4Beard, A Foreign Policy, pp. 41-43. See also Beard, The Idea, pp. 433, 69-70. 15Boston, 1890. l6Mahan, Influence of Sea Power, pp. 45—49, 87-88, 26. 45 and the neutral shipping which came to her shores. Neutrality was no protection in time of war.17 He recognized that the technological developments of the age of the steamship would inevitably bring America into relations with the outside world.18 Taking as axiomatic America's need for sea power, Mahan began to look at the world about him. He was a strong advocate of the Isthmian canal, the annexation of Hawaii and the Philippines for strategic as well as economic reasons. One of his articles entitled VAmerican Naval Power,"19 enumerated the reasons in addition to the ”cosmic tendency” for America's taking a role in world politics. Nations have international duties as well as rights, Mahan said. America was no longer physically isolated because of the changes in communications. Our commerce was growing. A strong navy would be needed if we were to maintain the Monroe Doctrine. We were now a Pacific power, and Japan had become a potential threat. Other nations had developed colonies for a variety of reasons, political and commercial, and somehow America l7Mahan, Influence of Sea Power, pp. 84-87. 18Mahan, Interest of America, pp. 146-48. 19 than, Interest of America, pp. 137-72; the article appeared in 1895. 46 would inevitably get involved in the process. Mahan, like Brooks Adams, also talked of taking over Britain's role in the world, or of helping her to police the world and spread Anglo-Saxon institutions, although he did not favor a formal alliance with Britain.20 "If a plea of the world's welfare seems surprisingly like a cloak for national self interest, let the latter be accepted frankly as the adequate motive which it assuredly is.921 As an extension of this reasoning, Mahan believed that America's welfare would serve the world when she adjusted her short range interests to accord with the proper long term view. Mahan, like others of his age, reflected a dualism between the traditionally religious and idealistic outlook of America and the realpglitik derived from the current scene and the new amorality of science.23 He was particularly skillful in interweaving the materialistic and idealistic arguments for expansion, and despite the fact that the 20Mahan, Interest of America, pp. 108-34. 21Mahan, Interest of America, p. 51. 22Mahan, Interest of Americay p. 112; Alfred T. Mahan, The Problem of Asia and Its Effect upon International Policies (Boston, 1900): pp. 1-3 passim. 23Henry Adams, The Education of Henry Adams (New York, 1931), is much concerned with this mental battle. 47 materialistic predominate, his moral and ideological arguments carry a conviction of genuine belief and do not seem to be simply window dressing, as Beard suggests.24 In addition to the Anglo-Saxon mission, Mahan was deeply concerned about the need to preserve and extend Christian civilization in the Orient. China held a special fascination for the age. It was represented as the last available market. Men were dazzled by the concept of such a large population under one government, and they tended to overlook the fact that this population lived in poverty and was ruled by a weak despotism that left much authority in local hands. In addition to its large space on the map, China had other attractions that tended to focus attention on it. It was an ancient civili— zation, and those who wrote about China had a respect for this civilization they did not accord to Africa or South America, other possible markets of the nineteenth century. There was a concern about what would happen to this civili— zation when it was set in motion by the more dynamic civilization of the West, particularly by the impact of western industrial economy; and how this revitalized Eastern 4Beard, A Foreign Policy, p. 46; a similar view is maintained by Robert Osgood, Ideals and Self-Interest in America's Foreign Relations (Chicago, 1953), pp. 32-39. 48 civilization (with its potential military power) would impinge on the west. This interaction of civilizations was viewed alternatively with alarm and with hope. Mahan on the whole viewed the prospect with alarm. He noted that the two civilizations were approaching each other in their ideas about material advantage (Japan had already grasped this concept from the West), but his great fear lay in the fact that the East lacked corresponding spiritual ideals. ”It is not merely that the two are in different stages of development from a common source, as are Russia and Great Britain. They are running as yet on wholly different lines, springing from conceptions radically different.”25 Whatever the shortcomings of Christianity, it had produced a common set of ideals that governed the conduct of even the agnostic in the West. These ideals posed some self-restraints on the materialistic grasping that had become prevalent in the West. Chinese civilization, as Mahan saw it, had no such restraints. In self defense, and as a duty, therefore, it was the mission of the West to indoctrinate the East with Christian ideals, as the British were doing in India.26 With the two civilizations 25Mahan, Interest of America, p. 228. 26Mahan, Interest of America, p. 244. 49 of East and west coming into contact and probably into conflict with each other, America would inevitably be involved in this struggle between civilizations. Mahan believed: It is essential to our own good, it is yet more essential as part of our duty to the commonwealth of people to which we racially belong, that we lodk with clear, dispassionate, but resolute eyes upon the fact that civilizations on different planes of material proSperity and progress, with different spiritual ideals, and with very different political capacities are fast closing together. Since ”conflict is the condition of all life”28 this meeting would breed battles and America would have to be prepared spiritually and materially._ In these global discussions, commentators sometimes had difficulty in deciding on which side Russia belonged. In the above quotations Mahan seemed to regard her as part of western civilization, but in The Problem of Asia, published three years later, Russia played the role of villain. Like Brooks Adams, Mahan saw two civilizations, one based on land power, Russia, the other, Britain and America, based on sea power, competing for the body of China. This conception recognized the existing conflict of interest between Britain and Russia extending from the Straits through 27Mahan, Interest of America, p. 263. 28Mahan, Interest of America, p. 268. 50 the entire Middle East to the Pacific. In discussing the conflict between Britain and Russia, Mahan evaluated the military and strategic position of all the powers in China, although he tended to overlook the complications arising from their relationship to each other in Europe. He hoped that by a rational estimate of the forces at work in China, an actual battle between the sea and land powers would be avoided. American policy should be based on a careful awareness of these international power relations. ‘Control of commerce was a factor of power open to sea powers that would help to sway the balance of power in their favor. 9 ’ ’The prize to the victor in this struggle of sea and land power was not just the commercial advantage of the China market, this was but a pawn in the game, the ”short term” goal, but the power to determine the future of civilization in China-—"the long term" aim. I The expansion of commerce, and the benefit resulting therefrom, are, however, only part of the objects that necessitate European pressure upon the China of our day. The close approach and contact of Eastern and Western civilizations . . . are matters which can no longer be disregarded, or postponed by any arguments derived from the propriety of non- interference, or from the conventional rights of a so- called independent state to regulate its own internal 29Mahan, Problem of Asia, pp. 49-55. 30Mahan, Problem of Asia, pp. 165-66. 51 affairs . . . . All that can profitably be attempted is to direct, by so shaping conditions that the higher elements of either civilization can act as freely as do the motives of pecuniary profit which, though perfectly proper, are lower as well as stronger. To achieve this freedom for the development of civilization, Mahan urged the importance of keeping China open to western ideas, an intellectual open door. China would have to be given time to evolve gradually toward a Christian and industrial civilization so that she did not erupt into revolution. Time was of the essence, and to gain time it might be necessary to use force. In Mahan's View the competition between nations in China actually helped to gain time for China to absorb the new civili- zation peacefully, and incidentally insured that China did not develop into a monolithic state like Russia, but developed regional differences corresponding to the spheres of the great powers. America should work cooperatively not only with Britain, but with France, Germany and Japan which he here classified as sea powers, to offset the Russian threat and preserve China, although Mehan opposed actual alliances. By following this policy America would benefit in the short 31Mahan, Problem of Asia, pp. 88—95. 52 term through commerce, and at the same time work toward the long term goal of preserving China and saving Western civili- zation. In opening China, Commerce and its gains, though not the worthiest and most benignant result, are the most obvious and convincing expression. In its train we may hope will follow those moral and spiritual ideals . . . in which alone can surely be found the happy renewal of Asia.32 A proper adjustment of the long term and short term View would benefit everyone. There must be the speculative forecast of the distant future, hand in hand with the consciousness of what at the moment is possible; and there must also be embraced in due relative proportions, the sense of primary duty to one's country and an unremitting regard to the real exigencies and needs of other people.33 Mahan and Brooks Adams were typical exponents of an age that was trying to fit the traditionally strong idealism of America into the brutal ”facts of nature” revealed by Darwin. Survival of the fittest and inevitable conflict in the affairs of men had the sanction of science and had to be accommodated in political thinking. The fallacies of applying biology to social life have since been pointed out, by Hobson among others, and today it is hard to realize 32than, Problem of Asia, p. 163. 33Mahan, Problem of Asia, p. 113. 53 the strength of Social Darwinism in the thought of the period. Yet in other respects the concept of the battle of civili- zations and ideologies has a very contemporary ring, and the introduction of the concept of power in international affairs perhaps had a salutary effect on American thinking about foreign policy. The idea of the importance of power in international affairs of course did not originate with Social Darwinism and was a lesson daily taught by the very competitive politics of imperialism, but by seeking to come to terms with the problem of physical survival and the question of the inevitability of conflict in the process of evolution, Americans were forced to focus attention on the problem of physical power in the world. Another generation was to pass by before Americanssrealized that moral righteousness alone did not win battles, although the relative weight to be given righteousness and battleships is still a disputed point in this country. But the writers at the turn of the century pointed out that if right was to win, it had better be mighty. One cannot discuss the intellectual outlook of late nineteenth century America without mentioning The Education of Henry Adams. Although the book was a personal and philosophical search for meaning in the modern world, abstruse in its irony and veiled references‘rather.than a 54 discussion of current politics, it caught important contemporary trends of thought. Many of its themes were echoed in the writers mentioned. Henry Adams was largely concerned with the impact of scientific ideas on the eighteenth century concepts of man, of history, of God. Henry Adams, unlike his brother Brooks, was not greatly impressed by the relevance of evolution to human affairs, but testified to its impact on his contemporaries.34 Although he mentioned Marx, he apparently did not consider economic conditions as a basic force in history nor did he regard Marxian thought of great significance in America. For his own interpretation of history Adams turned to physics and produced an almost mystical concept of forces in history. This theory found no followers in the political writers of the period, but represented a typical effort to find some all—pervading formula to account for the affairs of men. Adams contrasted the civilization of the Middle Ages with the civilization of the present, and made the dynamo, a product of science, the symbol of the current age. For him, too, power, not ideas, was what counted in the modern world. 34Henry Adams, Education, pp. 225-36. 55 He also was concerned with need for America to play a role in the world, and cheered John Hay's efforts in that direction. Hay was his hero.3 Adams' book reflected the general American affinity to England, despite its shortcomings, and the dislike of Russia, which for Adams represented the force of inertia in his scheme of things. ”The vast force of inertia known as China was to be united with the huge hulk of Russia in a single mass which no amount of new force could henceforth deflect."36 America represented energy and intensity. Which was to be stronger? Spring Rice's letters also echo many of the themes of Brooks Adams and Mahan, particularly the Anglo-Saxon mission, the ideological struggle with Russia and the rise and decay of civilizations. He wrote, of course, from the point of view of an Englishman, but in his letters there is no suggestion that there might be any divergence of interest between England and America. The central issue in the world was the duel between England and Russia. "England stands for liberty of thought and government and for the free 35Henry Adams, Education, pp. 365, 392, 422, 465, 504. 36Henry Adams, Education, p. 439. See also pp. 440, 408-11. 56 exercise of foreign enterprise throughout her empire. Russia is the personification of autocracy and the exclusion of foreign trade.”37 Germany, as an autocracy, would be ranged on Russia's side. Spring Rice was not quite sure that England alone was strong enough or prepared to make the sacrifices to defend herself against tyrannous Russia; but he looked to America and the other British dominions to save Anglo-Saxon civilization. In a typical expression of this view to Roosevelt in 1898 he wrote: I believe we should make a game fight of it. I only hope so -— but it may possibly end very badly. In that case, the fall of England itself will not mean the destruction or anything like it, of the work of England —- provided that the different branches of the race have not got divided by irreconcilable hatreds. For whether the British Empire goes or not, the English people throughout the world will make such a power as can never be destroyed. I don't care for black millions and red maps; what I care for, Which I learned from you, is a brave manly and honest people; the people who speak English through- out the world.38 In congratulating Senator Lodge on America's annexation of Hawaii, Spring Rice expressed his awareness of the decline of England: 3 . . . . . 7The Letters and Friendships of Sir CeCil Spring Rice, ed., Stephen L. Gwynn, 2 Vols. (Boston and New York, 1929), I, p. 404. 38SpringRice Letters, I, p. 270. 57 I think that there can be no doubt that there is an intention (and a natural one) to depose English civilization (I mean yours as much and more than mine) from the Pacific. The new order of things which is to replace it may be better; but it isn't ours, it is absolutely and wholly different from ours, and we have the right and the duty to defend what we most certainly have won on the American, Australian and Chinese coasts. But Spring Rice went on to express his hope that America would take over England's role: I don't believe that England, the island, is strong enough to defend English civilization alone -- and I have no sympathy whatever with the people who believe that English institutions, literature, language and greatness are courtiers at the throne of London. I believe they are common possessions, to be defended as they were won, in common —- and to be enjoyed in common too. And I welcome any step which America takes outside her continent because it tends to the increase of the common good.39 Spring Rice often returned to the theme that America must take over Britain's role as defender of English civilization. He wrote Lodge again in 1904, ”England is an artificial institution and the British Empire may perhaps be destroyed by a succession of well directed blows . . . I believe the United States to be the real fortress of our race and it is an infinite satisfaction to see its prosperity and power.”4 39SpringRice Letters, I, p. 249. 40Spring Rice Letters, I, p. 407. 58 It is to be seen from these quotations that Spring Rice was primarily concerned about Anglo-Saxon civilization and viewed autocratic Russia as the enemy. China and Japan were but pawns in this major power struggle. John Hay, too, was inclined to view things in this light but Roosevelt apparently took Spring Rice's views with a grain of salt. Several times in his letters he was careful to point out that America was not Anglo-Saxon but a mixture of races, as he himself was. Moreover there was bound to be a difference in outlodk between an Englishman who felt the Empire had passed its peak and an American who felt his country was on the rise. Despite these differences of opinion, Spring Rice undoubtedly encouraged a tendency among Americans to think in world terms and to see the world as a struggle of civilizations. Even writers who in general opposed the expansionist policy and Social Darwinism had points of resemblance to Mahan and Brooks Adams. Paul S. Reinsch, whose ideas are interesting in view of his later role in Chinese affairs, anticipated many of Hobson's arguments in his book World Politics at the End of the Nineteenth Century as Influenced by the Oriental Situation, although he did not present such a closely reasoned attack on imperialism and seemed to take 59 for granted American expansionist tendencies.41 The first part of the book was a general exposition of contemporary world situation, and the second dealt with "the true centre of interest in present international politics, namely China."42 ’Reinsch, like Hobson, viewed the contemporary imperialism as different from the past in that it was a conscious government policy, rather than a gradual development through the expansion of private trade or through the migration of peoples (as was the case of Russia in Siberia). This conscious policy was more apt to lead to wars, particularly as each nation wanted to ”civilize” the‘world.43 I Unlike the Social Darwinists he did not regard conflict as a necessary state of existence, but he did feel that the current imperialism was influenced by evolutionary concepts. In his View imperialism was caused by excessive nationalism, rivalry between nations, messianic ideas, and as a concomitant to these views, protectioist economic policies. ‘He recognized that the desire to protect investments played a large role in imperialism, but regarded this as an almost inevitable result of bad governments in 41Reinsch, pp. 309—10. 2 . . Reinsch, p. Vi. 43Reinsch, pp. 61-68. 60 the backward areas.44 Economic penetration was a method of imperialism, not a cause, nor was it a peculiar trait of capitalism."Badkward countries needed capital, and to get it order and stability had to be established somehow. "In this way, the real needs ofthe expanding human race are united with the self interest of capitalism to form a lever for expansion. ’Though true, it is a one sided View that imperialism is the selfish policy of capital.”45 Instead it was part of the struggle between civilization and barbarism, and a sad duty of the white race." In discussing the current situation in China he deplored the fact that political considerations had interfered with the development of the country. "It is unfortunate that political interference is constantly being invited in China on account of the insecurity which capital, unsupported by government backing, must necessarily feel.”46 The business syndicates therefore got involved in political intrigue which in turn made all commercial dealings politically suspect. Commerce became a tool of national rivalries. In his discussion of China, Reinsch was fully alive to the 44Reinsch, pp. 8-13, 34-40, passim. 45Reinsch, p. 42. 46Reinsch, p. 145. 61 complex interaction of politics and commerce, but seemed to suggest that, left to themselves, business and financial interests would be of service to China. Thus Reinsch, who foreshadowed many of Hobson's arguments, did not give economic considerations quite such a prominent position, and did not regard finance capital as totally villainous. Reinsch also anticipated many of Hobson's arguments against imperialism. In his opinion trade did not necessarily follow the flag, colonies did not pay, and imperialism had an adverse effect on domestic political reform.4.7 Reinsch showed greater affinity to his expansionist contemporaries in regarding the problem of China as essentially one of the interaction of civilizations. After discussing the national rivalries reflected on the China scene, he turned to the problem of the effect of the industrial revolution on China and the need for Chinese reform. Instead of the forceful Christianization of China advocated by Mahan as a defense for Western Civilization, Reinsch urged tact and held out hope for a peaceful merging of the best qualities of both civilizations, although he did not exclude the use of force to protect lives and property.48 47Reinsch, pp. 34—40, 71, 327-47. 48Reinsch, pp. 88—89, 194, 236-57. 62 Concerning America's role in the East, Reinsch seemed to take it for granted that she was involved, and urged only that she act with good motives and tact. He did not doubt that she had a right to share the riches of the Orient and he felt America also had a contribution to make to Chinese civilization. He differed from Mahan and Spring Rice in that he did not exaggerate this contribution into a sanctified Anglo-Saxon mission to preserve civilization. He recognized America's close political affinity with Britain, but realized that our material aims were not always akin. He warned against allowing Britain to draw us into her feud with Russia and so drive Russia out of the Western camp. Reinsch shared some of the general alarm about Russia but thought she might have a role in the East as a mediator between the two civilizations of which she was an amalgam.49 Thus Paul Reinsch, who eXhibited none of the symptoms of imperialist fervor nor the breast-beating nationalism of Adams and Mahan, still regarded it as inevitable that America would be drawn into world affairs; that China was the significant area of activity because she represented an ancient civilization which was just coming into contact with the west; that for better or worse the East and West would 49Reinsch, pp. 359-60, 206-21, 240. 63 influence each other; that America had a special affinity to Britain; and that Russia was a potential threat. Moreover, while he recognized the economic aspects of the China problem, he tended to regard these more as symptoms than causes of imperialism. It remains to be seen how the ideas discussed in this chapter influenced the thinking and policy of American statesmen with regard to China. CHAPTER III AMERICA'S ECONOMIC STAKE IN CHINA To judge the validity of the economic theory of imperialism as an explanation for American policy in China, it is necessary to look at America's economic relations with that country. The theory states that the surplus goods of a highly developed capitalist system need an outlet, that capital accumulates faster than the home market can absorb it, and that political interference and possible territorial annexation follow investment. While it is beyond the scope of this study to analyse the whole structure of the American economy to determine whether it had in fact reached the stage of finance capital, it is possible to get some picture of American investment in China and of the nature and the extent of her trade to discover whether in fact China was an important market and fieldibr investment. The picture is fairly clear concerning America's capital investment in China. It was small. Even Nearing and Freeman admit that America was not a great exporter of 1The view that the United States had reached the stage of ”finance capitalism” is expressed, for instance, in Arthur Meier Schlesinger, Political and Social Growth of the American People, 3rd ed. (New York, 1941), p. 297. 64 65 capital before 1900 "as the domestic demand for capital more than covered the available amount of investment surplus.”2 American investment in China can be compared to her total foreign investment, and also to the total of all foreign investment in China. One set of figures estimates all of America's investment in Asia in 1900 (including the Philippines, Japan, Australia, New Zealand as well as China) at $5 million, which would be just over 1 per cent of her total foreign investment of $455 million. Canada and Central America were the areas of largest investment, with $150 and $195 million respectively. By 1912 America's investment in China and Japan had risen to $50 million out of a total of $1,740 million, or roughly 2-1/2 per cent.3 C. F. Remer estimated the foreign debt of China on a different basis by including ”a reasonable valuation of all sources within China from which an income is received or is normally to be expected by persons who are not Chinese."4 2Nearing and Freeman, pp. 11—12. 3Beard, Idea, p. 209, citing figures from America's Direct Investments in Foreign Countries; Nearing and Freeman, p. 11, cite the same figures drawn from H. E. Fisk, Inter- AllygDebts. 4C. F. Remer, Foreign Investments in China (New York, 1933), p. 62. 66 This would therefore include properties held by the foreign colony in China and the resulting estimate is far greater than the estimate based simply on the income from capital investment in China. Remer's figures give the relative standing of American capital with that of other foreign capital. Again the American role is small. Remer estimated that in 1902 the total foreign investment in China was $787.9 million, of which America's share was $19.7 million or 2.5 per cent. The direct business investment he estimated at $17.2 million, of which about $10 million was in Shanghai. This included real estate values which could only be guessed at. American holdings of the Chinese government were $2.2 million, the amount of the bonds sold by the American China Development Corporation. In addition there was another $5 million of holdings in mission properties.5 By 1914 the figures for American investment had risen to: $42 million for business investment; $7.29 million for securities and government obligations; and $10 million for mission property. Excluding mission property, this was still only 3.1 per cent of the total foreign investment of 5Remer, Investments, pp. 76, 254—5, 259. 67 $1,610.3 million.6 In 1902 Britain, with 33 per cent of the total foreign investment, Russia (31.3 per cent) and Germany (20.9 per cent) were the largest investors; while by 1914 Japan (13.6 per cent) and France(10.7 per cent) drew close to Germany and Russia in proportion,although Britain was still the largest investor with 37.7 per cent of the total.7 In sum, it can be seen that the investment of all nations in China was a very small portion of total world investment and that America's portion was among the smallest. Moreover, although investment in China more than doubled from 1902 to 1914, America's share did not rise appreciably. This does not mean that there were not efforts made by Americans to attract more American capital to China. Nevertheless, the small amount invested by Western nations in China is remarkable and provoked Remer to ask the question: The capital has been available in the capital exporting countries of the west throughout the century, except for the period of the World War. It has been available at rates well below the rates of interest that have 6Remer, Investments, p. 274. 7Remer, Investments, p. 74. For the year 1931 Remer gives the proportion of each country's foreign investment devoted to China, and it is interesting that even at that late date China represented only 1.3 per cent of America's foreign investment, and only 5.9 per cent of Britain's, but it represented 81.9 per cent of Japan's total (pp. 77-78). 68 prevailed in China. Why has it not gone to China?8 Remer provided a reply to his own question. The answer lay in part in the political upheavals in China, but also’in part in the economic structure and traditions of the country which prevented the absorption of more capital. The history of the American China Development Corporation, the only large-scale business investment by Americans in the early years of the century, and the loan negotiations after 1908 provide some insight into the reasons why more capital was not invested in China. 'With American investment in China so small, it is very difficult to argue that her imperialist activity in that area was inaugurated to protect her investment. The figures on American trade with China present a more complicated picture than those on investment. American economic discussions about China at the turn of the century almost always spoke of China as a market for goods, not for money. A decade later much of the argument for investing money in China rested on the belief that investment would be needed to preserve America's share of the market for goods, rather than on a desire to invest for its own sake. Willard Straight wanted American investment in Manchuria to 8Remer, Investments, pp. 230-31. 69 build up the market as a political weapon against Japan. The contracts for railway supplies usually went to the country supplying the money. "Trade follows bonds,” as one observer put it. A similar situation prevailed in other fields.9 The economic argument for imperialism maintains that the over-production of domestic manufactured goods requires an external market. It was noted by Beard, and also by Brooks Adams, that about 1876 America changed from being an over-all importing nation to an exporting nation, that she began producing more goods than she could consume. There was also a gradual reversal from being an exporter to being an importer of raw materials and an exporter of manufactured goods, although there were considerable fluctuations in this pattern. This brought about a shift in the areas with which America traded, a decline in her trade with Europe and a rise in her trade with the under-developed countries.10 But if the pressure of over-production was the basic reason for the search for markets, one might expect this problem to 9Herbert Croly, Willard Straight (New York, 1924), pp. 237—38; George E. Anderson, Railwanyituation in China, Special Consular Reports, No. 48 (Washington, 1911), p. 31. 10Beard, Idea, pp. 246-55; Brooks Adams, p. 87-887 Nearing and Freeman, pp. 8-10. The Shaping of American Diplomacy, ed. by William Appleman Williams (Chicago, 1956), pp. 328-32. 7O grow progressively worse. Instead, despite the growth of the American economy, the proportion of exports over imports remained approximately constant in relation to the total amount of exportable goods, about ten per cent.1 Despite all the rosy dreams of the China market and its potential expansion, its actual value remained relatively small. Although China's trade about doubled between 1900 and 1914 (and again by 1931) it represented only a minute portion of the total world trade: 1.5 per cent in 1900 and 1.7 per cent at the beginning of the First World War. Of this small pie, Britain's slice declined from almost a monopoly with 85 per cent in 1871, but America's slice did not grow appreciably. It varied between 5 and 10 per cent of the total trade of China from 1871 to 1915, with the exception of a few years around 1905.12 In the early years a very small part of American exports went to all Asia, 1.7 per cent in the period 1876- 1880, a figure which rose to 3.9 per cent by 1896-1900. By 1910-14 it was 5.6 per cent, a still small but not insigni- ficant part of the total. Europe as an area of export declined from 83.1 per cent in the 1876-80 period to 62.3 llBeard, Idea, pp. 247-48. 12Remer, Investments, pp. 48, 261. 71 per cent by 1910-14. This confirms the idea that as America changed from an exporter of raw material to an exporter of manufactured goods her markets changed, but the process was not far advanced by 1914..13 Oriental imports played a larger role than American exports to the Orient in the American economy. They rose from 11.3 per cent of the total in 1876-80 to 15.3 per cent in the 1910-14 period. However, a large proportion of this import was from Japan.14 No reliable estimates exist for the value of American trade with China because the Chinese Maritime Customs registered goods from the port of departure and much of America's trade entered China from Canada or Hong Kong. The consul-general in Shanghai, John Goodnow, complained of this practice in January, 1899, noting that the Customs report cited American trade for that year variously as 12,420,302 taels and 18,362,307 taels. This was about a tenth of all foreign trade, whereas Goodnow calculated that American trade represented about a seventh of the total. His own calculation was that American goods which entered China in 1898 were l3Beard, Idea, p. 273. By 1932 American exports to the Orient constituted 18.1 per cent of the total, and to Europe, 46.8 per cent. 14Beard, Idea, pp. 281, 284. In 1932 Oriental imports represented 27.4 per cent, rivaling Europe's 29.4 per cent. 72 worth $20 million.15 In America's trade with China, manufactured cotton goods, particularly yard goods, were by all odds the most important item, and while the value of this trade was not of staggering proportions, it was worth protecting. Next in importance were kerosene and flour, followed by iron, particularly steel rails, and tobacco. There were other goods in small quantity. Of the industries involved in the China trade, this market was of vital importance only to the cotton manufacturers. American statistics put the total value of all exported cotton goods in 1899 at $20 million or more, of which about half went to China.16 The proportion of the cotton goods that went to China remained high throughout the period under discussion, reaching approximately $33 million out of a total of $47 million total export by 1905. In 5Consular Reports, Shanghai, General Records of the State Department, vol. 46, January 25, 1899, December 23, 1899. In 1899 the tael was worth 71 cents. These figures can therefore be translated: 12,420,302 taels, $8,116,614; and 18,362,307 taels, $13,037,237. 16The precise figures given by different sources vary, but the proportion sent to China is always approximately half. Statistical Abstract of the United States (Washington), 1899, Twenty-Second Number, p. 333; Monthly Summary of Commerce and Finance of the United States (Washington), December, 1900, p. 1513. 73 1906 the total amount of cotton goods exported dropped to $32 million of which half still went to China. By 1910—12 other markets were beginning to rival China to some extent, and in 1912 the value of yard goods that were sent to the Philippines ($5 million), actually exceeded that sent to China ($4.6 million). The total value of cotton yard goods exported in that year was more than $30 million. Throughout the period, there were great fluctuations in the extent of the China trade and the total trade.17 In addition to being a major source of exports to China, the cotton manufacturing industry was in a strategic political position to apply pressure on American policy makers. It was the major industry of the South, which held a weighted place in Congress, and was also a major industry in Massachusetts, the seat of Senator Henry Cabot Lodge, one of the foremost advocates of expansion” ’ In 1899 the cotton manufacturers of South Carolina wrote to Senator McLaurin (of Mississippi) stating that the cotton industry was the paramount manufacturing interest in that state, and that it produced almost exclusively for the China market. If the China market were cut, this trade l7Monthly Summary, December, 1906, p. 1128; December, 1912, p. 661. 74 would have to compete in the home market. Consul Goodnow in Shanghai cited this letter in a speech supporting the building of an Isthmian canal, which would shorten the trade route to China and hence reduce costs. He went on to stress the potential dangers of a slump in the Southern cotton industry in its effect on the delicate labor and race relations of the region.1 The cotton interests together with the members of the American China Development Company were the most active supporters of the open door policy. Despite this political power, the cotton interests did not in other respects meet the specifications of the economic theorists. Far from being a centralized, monopolistic industry, it was one of the most competitive in the nation, and much of the trade with China had been built up to meet an estimated demand rather than being a surplus dumped on a foreign market.19 There were certain special conditions about the cotton market in China that are worth noting. Cotton was one of China's main imports, representing up to 40 per cent of her total imports until 1905, after which it declined in relative importance although it was still 32 per cent of the total 18Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 46, December 23, 1900. 19Campbell, p. 20. 75 in 1913. Britain was the main supplier of this market, but the American share grew faster than Britain's. However, since America usually supplied the cheaper goods, her trade was more subject to the fluctuations which were caused by the general prosperity of China. If American prices were not sufficiently low, the Chinese reverted to their traditional homespun. Also, American goods felt earlier than British the competition of India and Japan.20 In the years after 1905 the Japanese competition was the main reason for the decline of America's cotton trade with China. Apart from any political pressures Japan used, she had a natural trade advantage in the fact that she was a buyer of raw Chinese cotton, and that she manufactured the cheaper grades of cotton goods. The cotton market was further complicated by the fact that China began to spin her own cotton, so that after 1903 the market for cotton yarns did not develop so fast as the market for manufactured cotton goods. Remer notes one final instability which applied to 20C. F. Remer, The Foreign Trade of China (Shanghai, 1926), pp. 91-94, 150-52; George E. Anderson, Cotton-Goods Trade in China, Special Consular Reports No 44, Department of Commerce and Labor, Bureau of Manufacturers (washington, 1911). pp. 11-12. 21Remer, Trade, pp. 86—87, 94, 150-51, 154. 76 all trade, and this was its highly speculative nature, due to the fluctuations in the value of silver, on which the tael was based. As a result many speculators entered the trade who were not reliable merchants.22 The fluctuations noted in the export of cotton to China were even more apparent with the other major American exports. About $4 million worth of kerosene was shipped to China and Hong Kong in 1899 out of a total American export of $54 million. In 1905 the figure rose to more than $7 million out of a total export of $71 million, yet in the following year dropped to just over $4 million out of a total export of $76 million. By 1910 and 1911 the total value of kerosene shipped to China was rivaling the value of cotton goods. Similar fluctuations can be found in the figures for tobacco, which did not rise much above $1 million in the best year, and steel rails. The same pattern prevailed with wheat flour. Only $87 thousand was exported to China in 1899, while $334‘ thousand was sent in 1900. Almost $2 million worth of wheat flour entered China in 1906, four times the amount of the previous year. In 1910 some $3 million worth of wheat 22Remer, Trade, pp. 78—79; Anderson, Cotton—Goods, pp. 11-12. 77 was shipped to China and Hong Kong, and this figure more than doubled in the following two years.23 A large proportion of America's exports to China, and perhaps as much as 90 per cent of American cotton goods, went to Manchuria before 1905.24 The market in Manchuria had grown spectacularly in the years before 1900 and there were great hopes that it would continue to expand. American goods were well established at the turn of the century, representing about a third of all foreign goods entering Manchuria. One estimate put the total imports from all countries into Manchuria in 1899 at $20 million.25 In supporting a plea for the establishment of an American consulate at Newchwang in 1900, Consul Goodnow in Shanghai forwarded some statistics on American trade in that port. American drills valued at 2,023,646 taels were sold in 1900, ten times as many as a decade previously; America sold cotton sheetings valued at 3,910,916 Haikwan taels. 23MonthlySummary, December, 1900, pp. 1523, 1509; December, 1906, pp. 1124, 1132, 1143, 1147; December, 1912, pp. 659, 663, 667, 668. 24Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 46, December 23, 1899. 2 . . 5Foreign Markets for American Cotton Manufactures, Special Consular Reports, vol. XXXVI (washington, 1905), pp. 256. 78 The amount of kerosene exported by America to Manchuria increased from 1,730,000 gallons in 1898 to 2,282,060 gallons in 1900. This would be only a small portion of America's total export to China in 1900 of about 46 million gallons of refined oils. The amount of increase was impressive if not the total figures, and the prospective railway development of Manchuria promised further increases if America could hold her share of the market.26 While the total amount of the China trade was not great, most contemporary reports on the market stressed the rapid growth of the market and the great potential for the future.27 Up to 1905 America seemed to be gaining at the expense of Britain who had been the largest supplier of China's needs. However, after that year America's proportion of China's total trade decreased somewhat.28 Some of the reason for this is indicated in the more sober contemporary reports. On the one hand American business men were not 26Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 47, November 27 and December 5, 1900. With the Haikwan tael valued at 74 cents in 1900 the above figures could be translated as: 2,023,646 taels, $1,497,488; 3,910,916 taels, $2,894,077. Monthly Summary, December, 1900, p. 1523. 27Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 47, November 27, 1900; Foreign Markets for Cotton, pp. 38, 252; Anderson, Cotton-Goods, p. 30. 28Remer, Trade, pp. 161-63. 79 pursuing the market as avidly as they might, or as one might expect if the domestic market were threatened with disastrous glut; on the other hand representatives in China were pointing out that the China market was something of a myth. There are many indications that Americans did not do everything they could to meet the foreign competition in China in the years before the political obstacles became too great. A 1905 report of the consul in Newchwang said: If American trade in Manchuria in cotton goods, kerosene and other lines assumes the extent to which the economic opportunities entitle it, there must be developed some banking association that will assist and support the trade and branches must be established in the principle trade centers of the country.29 He went on to cite the practices of the Japanese and Russian banks in the matter of credit and financing. Moreover the companies needed agencies and representatives in Manchuria. Catalogues would not do the job. The Hong Kong consul reported that there was not enough trade in cotton there to warrant a special study of the market by American manu- 30 facturers. The American Minister in Peking did not believe American businessmen had availed themselves of the opportunities 29Foreign Markets for Cotton, p. 248. 30Foreign Markets for Cotton, p. 256. 80 in China. Rockhill felt that Japan would maintain the open door in Manchuria after the Russian war, and that America could have equal rights in that region ”if they will avail themselves of [the rights]._ Unfortunately our people have not conducted their business in China as other nations do, especially the Japanese and Germans, establishing direct relations with their customers.” Most of America's trade was handled by Japanese or foreign firms, Rockhill continued, and our interest in products ceased the day they left the factories or American ports. ”This apparent ladk of interest is recognized by American business men with Whom I have spoken as deplorably short sighted and discriminates more against us than any other cause, be it Japanese or Chinese.”31 [The American ambassador in TOkyo, Luke E. Wright, was of another opinion. iHe felt the Manchurian market was decidedly limited in 1906. ”Even when Manchuria is opened to the trade of the world, I am inclined to think that the demand for foreign goods will be very disappointing for the reason that the territory has been thoroughly devastated , . . . - "3 by the two great armies carrying on their operations therein. 31Papers Relating to the Foreign Relations of the United States, 1906 (washington, 1907), pp. 255-56; Paul A. Varg, Qpen Door Diplomat: The Life of w; w. Rockhill (Urbana, 1952), pp. 83-90. 32§oreign Relations, 1906, p. 217. 81 In the same year the consul general in Shanghai was anxious to dispel some of the rosy dreams about the China market. There has been and there will be an enormous market in China for foreign goods. Furthermore it will grow greater as the slow but sure inroad of the foreign merchant and his ware progresses. But for the present at least it must be understood that this market is open to a limited few who produce the things wanted and that education is required before there can be anything approximating a general market.33 He pointed out that China had an ancient and conservative civilization and did not readily take to new products. Even in Shanghai, the center of foreign settlement, there were few foreign goods on show in the shops. Few Chinese wore foreign clothes, or used imported agricultural instruments. The same problem, a lack of business initiative and inherent limitations in the market, were noted again in 1911 in special reports on the markets for cotton and railway materials. One drawback of American cotton was its high cost. As a rule American fabrics are too good for the market and decreased sales are due almost alto- gether to the refusal of American cotton 33Consular Reports,Shanghai, vol. 53, No. 91; See also Remer, Trade, 234-7. 82 manufacturers to adapt their goods to the trade, to pack goods according to the market needs, and to meet competition in other ways.34 The author of the special report added the comment that foreign cotton merchants in China . . . state frankly that the cotton—goods market in the United States is so great, its demand so steady, the prices it pays so good, and its consumption so broad that American manufacturers will give no more than passing interest to any foreign market and will not make the effort necessary to secure foreign business until home conditions turn against them.35 He adds the usual word of caution, however, that they must not neglect the future. The railways which were to help increase the avail- ability of the China market did not necessarily work that way. The cost of transportation often added enough to the cost of an article to price it out of the market. Most imported goods were sold near the port of entry. In surveying the market for railway materials the same author had similar conclusions. ”At present there is an impression among foreigners in and about China that the opportunities for the sale of foreign goods is vastly over- estimated.”36 The money expended was out of proportion to 34Anderson, Cotton Goods, p. 15. 35Anderson, Cotton Goods, p. 30. 36Anderson, Railway, p. 30. 83 the business received. Perhaps this fact was better known than he realized and explains why American business was not more active in China. Yet he continued to hold out the carrot of the future, for he went on to say that businessmen should not give up. Only those in the market would be able to share in future benefits. The orders for materials usually went to the firm or the country of the consulting engineer. It will be seen from the figures of American investment and trade that while America had a small economic stake in China, it was in no respect one that would necessarily be decisive in determining political action, except in so far as America was acting with an eye to the future. At the turn of the century her business investments were with one exception small; her efforts to increase her investments were made largely to control future markets and to gain political influence. Her trade was of somewhat greater importance, but never so vast that it would constitute a sole motive for political action. And with the possible exception of the cotton industry, the China trade was never of decisive importance to the domestic economy. CHAPTER IV JOHN HAY AND THE FAR EAST The Open Door Notes of 1899 were one expression of America's wider participation in world affairs. Previous to that time American activity in China had been confined to spasmodic efforts to support trading rights and mission work, and by and large she followed the lead of the European powers. Those who adopted the economic theory of imperialism have regarded the Open Door Notes as but an extension of the previous efforts to help trade. Even many who have taken a more complex View of the roots of imperialism have clung to the idea that the Notes were solely designed to guarantee equality of commercial opportunity in a nation that was threatened with partition.l It is true that the Notes were widely supported by commercial groups interested in China2 and certainly the framers of the Notes were aware of the commercial importance of the policy, but there is much evidence to show that commercial benefit was not the sole or even the first consideration. The Notes were the result of the wider View lLanger, p. 687. 2Campbell, pp. 33-59, passim. 84 85 of America's role in the world that was expressed by publicists like Brodks Adams, Mahan and others. Concepts of prestige, strategy and balance of power entered the picture. Wide political considerations required the territorial and administrative integrity of China. Moreover, the economic historians often overlooked another pressure group in America that was at least as influential on public opinion as the business interests, namely the missionary societies. In 1900 there were some thousand to fifteen hundred missionaries in China with mission properties valued at something like $5 million;3 and Americans at home contributed another $5 million in support of spreading the gospel in China. This material investment was but an outward expression of a deep spiritual interest. Whatever the justice of their cause, American Christians cared deeply about saving Chinese souls and they too looked to government for help. John Hay, the man who at the time was widely credited with "saving” China,5 has been represented as the spokesman 3Remer, Investments, p. 251; A. Whitney Griswold, The Far Eastern Policy of the United States (New York, 1938), p. 61. 4Varg, p. 28. 5Tyler Dennett, John Hay; From Poetry to Politics (New York, 1933), p. 295; Henry Adams, Education, p. 392. 86 for big business in the era of the robber barons. It is true that his father-in—law introduced him to the business world, and by his marriage he became a wealthy man. He was at heart a conservative, not given to underdog causes and distrustful of labor, as he showed in his novel, The Breadwinners.6 But an equally strong portrait could be drawn of Hay as poet and dilettante. In his early years he became a noted poet and writer. After his marriage he became a businessman, but he abandoned the tedious society of Cleveland as soon as he could for the brighter world of Washington, where for a decade he held no public or business post. During his later life his closest associate was Henry Adams, no lover of American commercial values. Hay's biographer referred to Hay, Adams and Clarence King as ”a select circle of those who had retired from the game.".7 Another close friend, Sir Cecil Spring Rice, in 1887 referred to Hay as "the poet” and ”the best story teller I have ever heard,"8 not as a financier or businessman. Roosevelt, even in the later years when he had many reservations about Hay as a statesman, referred to him as ”the most delightful man to 6Dennett, pp. 240, 107-18. 7Dennett, p. 160; see also Henry Adams, Education, pp. 106, 315, passim. 8 . . Spring Rice Letters, I, p. 81. 87 talk to I ever met."9 Of course, neither of these extremes, Hay as robber baron or Hay as dilettante, ix; the whole picture. One must add the concepts of Hay as newspaperman, Hay as admirer of Lincoln, Hay as junior diplomat, Hay as loyal Republican. Hay has not left so complete a public record as some of his friends of his View of the world scene. Because of his intimacy with the Adams brothers, Mahan, Spring Rice and to some extent Roosevelt, one can imagine him taking part in luncheon conversations that surveyed the world scene in terms of an ideology similar to that of their books. He was, however, more of a pragmatist than theorist. He was a ”day to day man,"; whereas Henry Adams was interested in the influence of the past, Hay was more concerned with the present.1 Hay believed strongly in Anglo-American cooperation. He spent much of his term of office ironing out the differences between the two nations, and was accused of being an Anglophile for his pains. Behind his desire for practical 9The Letters of TheodonaRoosevelt, ed. Elting E. Morison, John M. Blum, John F. Buckley, 8 Vols. (Cambridge, Mass., 1951), VI, p. 1489. 10Dennett, pp. 165—66, 189. It should be noted that despite their similarity of outlook in world affairs, Henry Adams was a Democrat. 88 political cooperation with Britain, lay the belief in the Anglo-Saxon mission and the white man's burden. In one of his few public addresses, to a Lord Mayor's dinner in London in 1898, Hay spoke of Anglo-American relations: All of us who think cannot but see that there is a sanction like that of religion which binds us to a sort of partnership in the beneficent work of the world . . . . we are bound by a tie which we did not forge and which we cannot break; we are joint ministers of the same sacred mission of liberty and progress, charged with duties we cannot evade by the imposition of irresistable hands.ll Hay regarded it as a ”cosmictendency,’ whatever the immediate issue, that America would take a larger role in world affairs. This was the spirit of the age. Not only was expansion inevitable, but he believed it was a positive good, not a crass economic necessity. Growth was a ”fine expression of the American spirit” and a beneficent force in the world.12 ”When a nation exists,” Hay wrote, "founded in righteousness and justice whose object and purposes are the welfare of humanity, the things that make for its growth and the increase of its power, so long as it . . .13 is true to its ideals, are sure to come to pass . . .' 11Quoted in Dennett, p. 189. See also Dennett, pp. 212-13, 218-23, 240-41; Roosevelt Letters, VI, p. 1497. 12Dennett, p. 220. 13Quoted in Dennett, p. 278. 89 With such a view of history, an idealistic overtone to a China policy would certainly appeal to Hay. Hay was distrustful of Germany and anti-Russian.l4 His thinking probably resembled that of Spring Rice in regarding the world scene as a battle between the tyrannies and the democracies. While Hay believed in expansion, in general, his precise reasons for the open door policy can only be guessed at. At the end of August, 1899, he asked Rockhill to "submit the project to him on the steps which should be taken by the United States at once to insure our commercial interests.”15 This was evidently in response to the agitation that was going on among United States business interests to "do something” about China. It is clear that this pressure merely provided a political opportunity for Hay to act rather than forcing him to act, for he had favored a statement on the open door ever since the British government had suggested a joint statement in March,1898. His precise motives for supporting the British suggestion in 1898 are l4Dennett, p. 384-87; Roosevelt Letters, VI, p. 1497; Griswold, pp. 55, 60. 15Quoted by Harvey Pressman, ”Hay, Rockhill and China's Integrity, a Reappraisal,” Papers on China, from the East Asia Regional Studies Program, Harvard University, ‘Vol. 13 (December, 1959), p. 67. 90 not known but since he was in London—-or more precisely Egypt—-at the time, it may be assumed that his support of the British move was not in direct response to American business pressure. It was far more likely part of his general belief in Anglo-American cooperation.l6 It is recognized today that the Open Door policy ‘was not so distinctly Hay's work as his contemporaries believed. And if there is some question whether Hay was motivated by a commercial outlook, there is little room for doubt that his chief adviser on Far Eastern matters, William W. Rockhill, was not personally interested in commercial advantage. He had joined the diplomatic corps in Peking in order to study Tibetan and left when his superior felt his studies were interfering with his work. He had a strong interest and attachment to oriental civilization, though he was by no means sentimental about China. His attitude could perhaps best be defined as paternalistic. Well aware of the corruption of the Chinese government, he felt that the Chinese should be pressed to reform.17 However, saving China for its own sake was not his only consideration. l6Dennett, pp. 285-86; Griswold, pp. 43-46, 51-52. l7Varg, pp. 11-13, 29-30, 120-21. 91 The United States had now spread across the continent to the Pacific coast and already had a foothold in the Philippines. To maintain a strong hand in the Pacific it was important to keep the European powers and their long- standing feuds at arms length. Americans were already concerned about the meeting of Russia and America. In 1867 we had acquired Alaska from Russia. 'With the acquisition of the Philippines, Rockhill said, ”the maintenance of the balance of power in Asia, in which the integrity of the Chinese Empire was of paramount importance, acquired sudden and great interest for us, and that the logical policy of the United States would be to insure its maintenance became at once apparent to all.”18 A few years later the war scare of 1907 from a newly powerful Japan showed how alive Americans were to a threat on their flank from the other side of the Pacific. The third person directly involved in the Open Door Notes was the Englishman, Alfred E. Hippisley. Although Griswold maintains that Hippisley was anxious to enroll America's support for Britain's policy of the open door19 18Speech entitled ”The Open Door" delivered Feb. 19, 1900, quoted in Pressman, p. 72. 92 it seems more likely in view of the fact that he had been in China with the Maritime Customs since 186720 that he was concerned with China for its own sake. He certainly had no interest in promoting American business. George Kennan even felt that Hippisley was directing his policy against Britain, which was not acting fairly in customs dealings with China.21 Certainly there was much indication that Britain had abandoned the policy of the Open Door. In response to the Russian seizure of Port Arthur, the British took Weiheiwei, and the Anglo-Russian railway agreement of 1899 was a frank recognition of spheres of influence in China. A little later the Anglo-German Agreement of 1900 and the Anglo-Japanese Alliance gave a further indication that Britain had abandoned a clear cut policy of the open door. The Anglo-German agreement, while proclaiming the open door, in effect gave each country a right to share in the other's sphere of influence, and by excluding Manchuria appeared to recognize Russia's rights there. The Anglo- Japanese Alliance in effect gave Japan a free hand in Korea, and made no commitment to preserve Manchuria. Rockhill 20Varg, p. 29 21George F. Kennan, American Diplomacy 1900-1950 (Chicago, 1951), pp. 27-32, 36. 93 considered England to be as great an offender in China as Russia herself.22 President McKinley's conversion to the more active policy in China was the final and decisive step in its execution. He was evidently convinced by the arguments put forth by Jacob Gould Schurman on his return from the Philippines and by those of the Rockhill memorandum, and he was encouraged to hope for the success of the policy by the Tsar's ukase making Talienwan a free port. The evolution and purpose of the Open Door Notes can be seen in the Hippisley-Rockhill correspondence of July and August, 1899. This correspondence makes it clear that Hippisley was anxious to prevent further encroachment on Chinese territorial integrity but realized the existing spheres could not be abolished. He first proposed that the Chinese treaty tariff should apply to all merchandise entering the spheres of influence and that the treaty ports should not be interfered with.24 Rockhill stated clearly in his reply that he ”would like it [the United States] to make a declaration in some form or other which would be understood by China as a pledge on our part to assist in maintaining 22Langer, pp. 777, 782; Varg, p. 29. 23 . Griswold, pp. 68—72. 24Griswold, pp. 65—66. 94 the integrity of the Empire."25 Rockhill was dubious whether the administration was ready to take such a step. The best that could be devised was to add to the first measures proposed by Hippisley the extra proviso that China herself should collect the treaty tariff in the spheres of influence. This would serve to strengthen the Chinese administrative control in her own territory.2 The purpose of the Open Door Notes was expressed in Rockhill's memorandum to Hay setting forth the proposals. Such an agreement would, he said: (1) secure an open market throughout China; (2) remove a source of conflict between the Powers and so help to re-establish confidence; (3)7Prepare the way for concerted action by the Powers to bring about the reforms in Chinese administration and the strengthening of 25Griswold, p. 67. 26Varg argues that Hippisley added this proviso in response to Rockhill's desire to make some sort of declaration in support of China's territorial and administrative integrity (p. 32). Pressman argues that Hippisley was not influenced by Rockhill in this suggestion and did not intend that this proviso be a step to ensure the integrity of China, but had expected the American government to make an entirely separate statement to this effect (PP. 68-72). 'What Hippisley intended by the statement is perhaps immaterial to an under- standing of the intentions of American policy. It is how Rockhill interpreted Hippisley's suggestion that is important. From his memorandum to Hay of August 23, 1899, it seems clear that he had accepted the Chinese collection of the tarrif as a means to save Chinese jurisdiction in the spheres. 95 the Imperial Government recognized on all sides as essential to the maintenance of peace,”; and (4) "It furthermore has the advantage of insuring to the United States the appreciation of the Chinese government who would see in it a strong desire to arrest the disintegration of the Empire and would greatly add to our prestige and influence in Peking.”27 The purpose is again stated clearly in the letter sent by Ambassador Choate to Lord Salisbury in which the proposal for the open door is given. Choate's letter is a paraphrase of Hay's letter to Choate. After an introductory paragraph about commercial rights in China, he states: While the Government of the United States will in no way commit itself to any recognition of the exclusive rights of any power within or control over any portion of the Chinese Empire, under such agreements as have recently been made, it cannot conceal its apprehension that there is danger of complications arising between the treaty powers which may imperil the rights insured to the United States by its treaties with China. It is the sincere desire of my Government that the interests of its citizens may not be prejudiced through exclusive treatment by any of the controlling powers within their respective spheres of interests in China, and it hopes to retain there an open market for all the world's commerce, remove dangerous sources of international irritation, and thereby hasten united action of the powers at Peking to promote administrative reforms so greatly needed for strengthening the Imperial Government and maintaining the integrity of China, in which it believes the whole Western world is alike concerned.28 27Diplomacy, ed. Williams.pp. 436—40. 28Foreign Relations, 1899, PP. 133-34. 96 Another indication that the United States intended the notes to go further than upholding commercial rights was a statement Hay made to Minister Conger in Peking, March 22, 1900. In telling Conger to press the Chinese government to protect foreigners from the Boxers, Hay said: In submitting this to the Yamen you will avail your- self of every opportunity to impress upon it that this Government, by the recent assurances which it has obtained from the various great powers holding leased territory or areas of influence in China, concerning freedom of trade in said regions and the maintenance therein of China's rights of sovereignty, has obtained thereby a renewed assurance of the policy of the treaty powers not to interfere with the integrity of the Chinese Empire.29 Since the Open Door Notes themselves were intended to gain support for the territorial and administrative integrity of China, the circular of July 3, 1900, was simply a clearer statement of a policy already in effect rather than a new departure made necessary to protect commerce from the new threat of China's partition as a result of the Boxer rebellion. Throughout the Boxer Rebellion and the ensuing negotiations, America tried hard to be fair to China while protecting her own nationals in China. In the early days of the Boxer attacks, Hay even went so far as to make 29Foreign Relations, 1900, p. 111. 97 sure that the Christians had at no time provoked the Boxers.3O Conditions in China by July, 1900, were so chaotic that there was danger that the Great Powers, particularly Russia, would use the suppression of the Boxer revolt and the rescue of the legations in Peking as an excuse to take over slices of Chinese territory. Since America had troops in China, it is conceivable that she herself could have established a sphere.31 Instead she exerted what pressure she could to uphold the territorial and administrative integrity of China. This was done not only by the July Circular rejecting any intention of annexing territory, but also by maintaining the fiction that America was not at war with China but only with the Boxers, and by isolating the fighting to the North through the assistance of the Viceroys of Nanking and Hankow. It was at the instigation of these Viceroys that America continued to recognize the Manchu dynasty on the condition that officials guilty of abetting the Boxers be punished. The Viceroys maintained that any attack on the Manchus would bring war to all China.32 30Foreign Relations, 1900, p. 111. 31That this was not a totally remote possibility was shown by Hay's endeavors to get a naval base at Samsah Bay in November, 1900. 2Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vols. 46 and 47 passim; Chester C. Tan, The Boxer Catastrophe (New York, 1955), pp. 83-91; Dennett, p. 299. 98 During the long, tedious and complicated negotiations for the Boxer protocol, Rockhill as the United States Commissioner, continued to fight for the American policy, and to use the occasion to press for reforms. He was not entirely successful. In a report to the Senate he summarized his accomplishments on four main issues.33 First, America believed that China herself should determine the punishment for guilty officials once the chief culprits were punished. Rockhill did manage to hold within bounds the lengthy list of culprits the Powers submitted to China for punishment. Secondly, America opposed any plan that promised long occupation of China by foreign troops or the creation of an international fort in Peking. America preferred to see a strong Chinese government which could be held responsible for maintaining order. This was partly on the pragmatic ground that foreign troops could not protect all foreign property in China under any circumstances.34 In this aim America was successful. As a third point, America was anxious for changes in court ceremonial and the creation of 33Foreign Relations, 1901 Appendix, pp. 3-7. 34Foreign Relations, 1901 Appendix, p. 82. As early as August, 1900, the American Minister in Peking had shown concern at the hardship foreign troops would bring to China because of the food shortage and later he stated their with- drawal would benefit China. Foreign Relations, 1900, pp. 199, 240. 99 a ministry of foreign affairs to facilitate China's relations with foreign powers. On this she also gained her point. On a fourth point America was not so successful. She wanted the indemnity to be paid to the Powers set at a lump sum to include the claims of all powers and not to exceed the ability of China to pay. The indemnity would then be divided among the Powers in proportion to their losses. America also wanted the debt paid by bonds at 3 per cent over a thirty to forty year period; to be secured in such a way that they did not create a financial crisis for China and so endanger her control over her own finances. This last point was the most crucial and most controversial, and the one most connected with the integrity of China. Although Rockhill was able to get a fixed sum established, he was not able to keep the indemnity within the sum America considered reasonable because she was supported in this only by Japan. America also secured payment by bonds, but the rate of interest was revised upward to accommodate Japanese objections. The Powers were anxious to secure the indemnity by an increase of the customs tariff. . . . The United States mindful of the furtherance of lawful commerce in China in the interests of the world and believing that no opportunity should be lost to secure to foreign trade all the facilities its vast importance entitles it to, and that any additional tax on trade should be met by commercial compensation 100 on the part of China of equal value, declined to consent to the above increase [to 5 per cent] of the customs tariff on imports unless (1) all the treaty powers and China agree to cooperate in the long desired improvement of the water approaches to Shanghai and Tientsin and (2) that specific duties should be substituted to the present ad volarem ones in the tariff on foreign imports. Both of these conditions were ultimately agreed upon.35 Rockhill had little support in his efforts to use the opportunity afforded by this general discussion of Chinese finances to press for reforms in Chinese trade practices. For decades foreigners had complained about the vagaries of Chinese internal taxes, particularly the likin. Rockhill opposed any increase in China's tariff until there were compensating reforms in the likin. He was also anxious to gain the right for foreigners to reside in the interior, to revise the inland navigation rules, and to have the Chinese create a bureau of mines.36 Russia, France and Germany were more interested in territory than in trade with the interior, and wanted the tariff raised to provide revenue more quickly for the payment of the indemnity. Although 35Foreign Relations, 1901 Appendix, p. 6. It todk another five years to set up the Whangpo Conservancy Board to improve the water approaches to Shanghai. The final obstacle was China's desire to undertake the task herself, and the United States supported her in this aim. Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 50, No. 579; vol. 52, No. 86 passim. 36ForeignRelations, 1901 Appendix, pp. 190-91. 101 Britain opposed Russia's suggestion for raising the tariff to 10 per cent ad valorem, she accepted a raise to 5 per cent without compensating commercial advantages, thus giving Rockhill little support in his efforts. The exigencies of European politics, always in the background of Far Eastern affairs, impelled England to cooperate with Germany on this issue, as well as on the question of the size of the indemnity.37 On the surface America's efforts for the abolition of the likin might well be conceived as another attempt to gain advantage for American commercial interests. But if it helped American trade, it would also strengthen China's administration by setting her finances on a sounder basis. Any increase in her trade would raise her revenues. However, there is some evidence that American merchants did not care about the abolition of the likin. In 1902 when the powers were meeting to work out the revision of the Chinese treaty tariff, a group of American businessmen met in Shanghai to consider the question, and opposed the proposal to increase the Imperial CustomStxalS per cent ad valorem in consideration of the abolition of the likin. They pointed out that most 37Foreign Relations, 1901 Appendix, pp. 169, 171-73, 175, 227-29, 252-53, 275-78. 102 of the likin was collected in Central and Southern China, whereas most American trade was in the North. The net effect of the proposal would be to raise rates for American goods at entry with no compensating advantage in transit. There was an added reason in their cynical belief that should the likin be abolished, a worse tax would take its place. America's major diplomatic task during the Boxer negotiations had been to hold the powers together in a unified front to deal with China in order to prevent separate agreements by each at the expense of China. One indication of America's willingness to give up immediate advantage for the purpose of maintaining a united front is indicated in a report by Rockhill. It has been rumored here of late that some American capitalists were willing to supply China with all the money she might need in her present embarrassment, on condition that the administration of certain of China's present revenues be farmed out to them for an extended term of years. Any such attempt to secure control over the large part of China's revenues and thereby over the Government of China, would be strongly opposed by all the other powers out here, and I think not unnaturally. So strong I think would be the opposition that it seems to me it would be quite impossible to carry out this plan. The development of China's resources and improvement in her methods of administration will tend more than 38Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 48, No. 389. 103 anything else to increase her commerce, and will, therefore, be ultimately much more beneficial to us and the world at large than any other plan which can be thought of for the settlement of its new financial obligations.39 Although Rockhill's remarks were instigated by a rumor only, they are evidence that he was not interested in helping American capitalists at the expense of China and cooperation with the Powers. The policy of cooperation was considerably hindered by the considerations of European politics which were ever present in the minds of all but Japan. England in particular was in an exposed diplomatic position, and had been searching for allies since 1898.40 She was no longer strong enough in the East to dominate the situation single handed. She was faced with Russian opposition throughout the Middle East and India, and tried to cooperate with Germany in Chinese affairs. This limited cooperation found expression in the Anglo-German agreement of October 1900. Russia was a dominant force in Europe, strengthened by her French alliance, and as the only European power contiguous to China she held a particularly strong position, although the Trans-Siberian Railway was not completed until 1903 and 39Foreign Relations, 1901 Appendix, pp. 113-14. 4OGriswold, pp. 37-47; Langer, pp. 461—80. 104 the Russian population was not large in Eastern Siberia. Germany was also in a weak diplomatic position, and vacillated between reaching an agreement with England and with Russia.41 Although she cooperated with England in China, Germany also was anxious to placate Russia, and to encourage her Far Eastern ambitions in order to divert her attention from European affairs. Germany was so arrogant with her military maneuvers and her demands for indemnity that China felt she had to lean on Russia for support. Japan was already concerned about Russian intentions in the Far East and urged China to resist the Russian demands.42 Japan had not yet become a major power and stood to gain more by an open door policy in China than by any partition. She was the only power to give any support to the American position in the Boxer negotiations, It was perhaps because of this support that Americans were slow to believe in Japan's aggressive intentions after the Russo-Japanese war. During and after the Boxer negotiations, Russian encroachments in Manchuria presented an immediate challenge to the Open Door policy. During the negotiations Russia used her strong diplomatic and strategic position to try and 41Langer, pp. 700-05. 42Tan. pp. 175—76, 199, 206-13. 105 reach a separate agreement with China concerning her position in Manchuria. She had used the excuse of the Boxer outbreaks to take military control of Manchuria, ostensibly to protect her railroad, and by October, 1900, had control of the three Eastern provinces. The Tseng—Alexeiev agreement of November, 1900, was the first fruit of Russia's efforts for a separate agreement. When the Chinese refused to accept this agreement, Russia's demands were revised in the new year. Japan was the most vocal opponent of these demands, protesting both to China and to Russia, and Britain joined in protesting to China. Japan, worried about the future of Korea should Russia gain control of Manchuria, was even ready to go to war with Russia if she could be assured of British and German support should France come to the aid of her ally, Russia. Although Britain did not agree at this time (March, 1901), Japan's attitude provided the seed for the Anglo—Japanese Alliance which was concluded a year later.43 Within China the Viceroys of Nanking and Hankow, who had kept open the channels of communication with the Powers during the Boxer revolt, again served as a link with the Powers and urged the United States to join the British— Japanese protests. They also pressed their own government 43Langer, pp. 695-96, 711, 716-23; Tan, pp. 206-10. 106 to resist Russian demands.44 The opposition of these Viceroys to Russian encroachment in these years might be considered an early indication of the rising nationalism in China. Under the pressures of the Viceroys and the Powers, the Chinese Government refused the Russian demands for an agree- ment until after the Boxer protocol had been settled. Russia was forced to back down on her demands but her troops remained in Manchuria. A tentative agreement in October, 1901, was rejected by China, and the death of the Chinese statesman Li Hung Chang in November further delayed agreement. Moreover through 1901 the Russians themselves were vacillating between the policies of aggression and retraction, and were awaiting the outcome of negotiations with the Japanese for an accord on Korea and Manchuria. The Japanese, however, finally rejected a Russian rapprochement in favor of the English alliance.45 Again in January, 1902, the Russians and Chinese were about to reach agreement on the terms for the evacuation f of Manchuria, only to have the Chinese reject the proposals after protests, this time from the United States. In April, 1902, agreement was finally reached by which the 44Tan, p. 193. 45Langer, pp. 723, 748-49, 751, 763-71. 107 Russian withdrawal was to take place in three phases. Only the first phase, in October, 1902, was accomplished due to the changes in policy of the Russian government. By the time designated for the second withdrawal, April, 1903, the Russians were making new demands on China.46 Against this background of these events, America began to take a more active part in Manchuria. In the years from 1898 her interest in Manchuria had grown with the increase in her trade in that region. This trade, though not large, had increased phenomenally. American goods represented about half the foreign trade in the port of Newchwang. Commercial affairs there had been in the hands of an Englishman, but it was felt that an American would be more diligent in furthering American commerce. In a report giving a variety of statistics to show the rapid growth of trade from 1897 to 1899, the consul at Chungking also noted the political problems of Russia's presence. ”That section of China has become a center of considerable political importance,” he wrote, ”and our country should have a representative there to guard both our industrial and political interests. We have consulates in China at points 46Langer, p. 781; Foreign Relations, 1903, pp. 53-54. 108 where our commercial and political affairs are not nearly as extensive as at Newchwang.”47 This view was supported by the American Association of China. "Unless speedy action is taken, the development of present conditions will strongly threaten our commercial future in Manchuria."48 With the designation of Henry B. Miller as consul at Newchwang in June, 1901, America had an official observer on the spot. Through 1902 and 1903 reports began to come in concerning Russian interference with business operations. In 1902 there were complaints about Russian control of the telegraph system.49 By March, 1903, it was noted that Russian goods were entering Manchuria free of Chinese customs; that they were applying discriminatory rail rates; that Russia was setting up her own courts and forcing Americans to be tried in these rather than the consular courts.50 However, in addition to preserving American trade in Manchuria, America was genuinely anxious to break the Russian hold in the Eastern provinces. There was no 47Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 47, Nov. 27, 1900, enclosing a report from Henry B. Miller at Chungking. 48Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 47, Dec. 4, 1900. 49Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 48, Jan. 21, 1903; Foreign Relations, 1902, pp. 916-26. 50Foreign Relations, 1903. Pp- 48—51. 109 consideration of a policy of appeasing Russia in exchange for economic entrance into Manchuria. Through 1901 and 1902 the United States relied mainly on protests to China about making any agreement that infringed on American rights. In December, 1901, Conger reported that Russia and China had reached an agreement for a three- phased evacuation of Manchuria, and that England and Japan had urged the Chinese not to sign. Hay replied that the United States must expect China to make no treaty that impaired her territorial integrity or interfered with the legitimate interests of the United States. By January, 1902, China had accepted the agreement with Russia which permitted China to develop Manchuria herself but stipulated that if outside capital should be needed (which surely would be the case) she must apply first to the Russo-Chinese Bank. The open door was to be maintained at the Treaty ports. Conger again cautioned the Chinese to uphold the treaty rights of other powers; Britain and Japan had also protested. In addition, in February Hay sent a memorandum to China, Russia and the other powers objecting to the award of exclusive rights to such a corporation as the Russo—Chinese bank. and pointed out that it impaired China's sovereign rights 51William Appleman Williams, American Russian Relations, 1781-1947 (New York, 1942), pp. 36-37. 110 and her ability to meet her international obligations.52 Hay's policy with respect to Russia's challenge in Manchuria has been called a retreat from the advanced position of the July Circular upholding China's territorial and administrative position to the more modest position of the Open Door Notes which recognized the spheres of influence.53 Since, as we have seen, the Open Door Notes indicated an intention to support the territorial and administrative integrity of China, the July Circular was merely a much stronger statement of this purpose made in circumstances when there was a renewed threat to China's integrity, but also when it was possible to hope for cooperation from the European Powers whose legations were alike threatened in Peking. It might be said that the July Circular expressed a hope rather than an intention to act. However, it is true that both Hay and Roosevelt admitted that Russia had special interests in Manchuria and hoped only to limit the extent of her control of the region to allow American trade.54 It seems likely that the 52Foreign Relations, 1902, pp. 271-75. 53 . Griswold, p. 84; Bennett. p. 403. 54Griswold, pp. 87-88; Howard K. Beale, Theodore Roosevelt and the Rise of America to World Power (Baltimore, 1956). pp. 193, 271. 111 shift in emphasis from the July Circular to the Manchurian policy after the Boxer Protocol reflected the influence of Roosevelt who had succeeded to the Presidency after the sending of the Circular. The realistic recognition of the power situation in 1902-03 was similar to his policy toward Japan in Korea and Manchuria after the Russo-Japanese war, and his attitude to Knox's policy in 1910. Roosevelt wrote in 1903 that . . we disclaim any intent to interfere with the political future of Manchuria. All we ask is that our great and growing trade shall not be interrupted and that Russia shall keep its solemn promises . . . . We have always recognized the exceptional position of Russia in relation to Manchuria. We have done nothing to interfere with her progress and her legitimate aspirations. We have only insisted upon that freedom of access and of opportunity for our commerce which has been guaranteed to us by the agreement of the whole civilized world including Russia . . . .55 He wrote to Hay that though the mendacity of Russia was appalling, there was little America could do as she could not as yet fight. "I hate being in the position of 56 seeming to bluster without backing it up." As Russia continued to hang on in Manchuria and to threaten,America sought to probe Russian intentions and met 55Roosevelt Letters, III, pp. 497-98. 56Roosevelt Letters, 111. p. 478. 112 with persistent denials by the Russians of any demands on China.57 America's use of force in Manchuria was out of the question, although Roosevelt was sufficiently angry at Russia's "mendacity" to consider it. He wrote to Hay in July, 1903, "And I wish, in Manchuria, to go to the very limit I think our people will stand. If only we were sure neither France nor Germany would join in, I should not in the least mind going to extremes with Russia."58 Since ”extremes" would have been unacceptable to the American public, Hay relied on two other instruments to counter the Russian pressures. The first was the Anglo-Japanese alliance, signed in February, 1902, which was directed against Russia. The Anglophile tendencies of the American policy makers were sufficiently strong so that this alliance was hailed with much enthusiasm, and it was some time before it was clear that it did not always work in the interests of America or that it did not apply to Manchuria.59 Roosevelt regarded America as almost a silent partner to the agreement. and . . O indeed in 1904 Japan did "fight our battle” against Ru55ia.6 57Varg, pp. 52—56. 58Roosevelt Letters. 111. p. 532. 59Langer, p. 782. 60Bea1e, p. 171. 113 Ambassador Choate wrote to Hay, "It seems to me greatly to fortify the policy of the 'open door' and goes far to secure the independence and integrity of the Chinese and Korean empires."61 The other instrument of Hay's policy was the Commercial Treaty of 1903, which like the Open Door Notes had a dual purpose, to help American trade and to counter political pressures of other powers, in this case Russia, on China. The specific device to counter Russia's political control in Manchuria was the attempt to open new treaty ports in that region. Russia clearly showed her hand by making new conditions with China stipulating that China open no new treaty ports before she evacuated Manchuria. China also was to employ no foreigners except Russians in her public services, and the customs collected at Newchwang, the chief port of entry for American goods, were to be deposited in the Russo-Chinese bank.62 At the same time Russia persistently denied in Washington and St. Petersburg that she had put any such pressure on China. This was the “mendacity" that so angered Hay and Roosevelt.63 China 61Foreign Relations, 1902, p. 513. 62 . . Foreign Relations, 1903, p. 53. 63Foreign Relations. 1903, p. 56 ff; varg, pp. 51-58. 114 refused Russia's demands, but she also refused to make the agreement with America on the excuse that she could not open new ports until the Russians had evacuated Manchuria.64 America refused to accept such a condition, insisting that "China has the recognized right to open whatever ports she pleased in her sovereign territory.”65 America was ready to delay signing the treaty until October 8, the day the Russians were supposed to begin withdrawal from Manchuria. provided the article designating the treaty ports was written into the Commercial Treaty and was not made a separate agreement, as China had wanted. The opening of the ports was not to be dependent on the Russian withdrawal, however.66 The treaty opened Antung and Mukden to foreign trade. America had worked to include Harbin, a Russian stronghold, but China refused. A discussion of Hay's policy in China is not complete without some consideration of the case of the American China Development Company which actually spanned several adminis- trations. This episode is frequently cited by economic historians in support of their thesis that American policy 64Foreign Relations, 1903, p. 66. 65 . . Foreign Relations, 1903, p. 71 66Foreign Relations. 1903, pp. 70, 71-73. 115 was designed solely to further American economic interests in China. The case was certainly damaging to American relations with China, but there are many ambiguities con- cerning the government's precise intentions, and even though America supported the company, there is no evidence that she did so because surplus capital threatened the domestic economy. The American China Development Company was incor- porated under New Jersey law in December, 1895, with the purpose of financing Chinese railways. A number of prominent financiers were stockholders. It began to negotiate with the Chinese government in 1896. Charles Denby, the American Minister in Peking, wanted to support American business in China but was restricted by his instructions from‘Washington. These instructions varied with the changes of Secretaries of State from a hands—off policy to a specific promise to assist American firms if their activity was not detrimental to other American companies. After the company had made its preliminary contract in April, 1898, to build a railway from Hankow to Canton, it sought State Department help to protect the concession against foreign interference, parti- cularly by France. Secretary of State Day refused on the ground that "the American government had always declined to 116 guarantee private contracts with foreign powers."67 Soon after the preliminary agreement was signed the company found that more money would be required than originally anticipated, and while surveys were being made of the route, negotiations were resumed to write a supple- mentary agreement. The company wanted to take this opportunity to gain extensive mining rights and concessions for branch lines, but the Chinese opposed these requests. Sheng Hsuan—Huai, Director General of the Chinese Railway Bureau, was anxious to reach agreement with the Americans, however, to prevent the concession from falling to either the British or the Belgians. In July, 1899, the company appealed to Hay, who had become Secretary of State, to back up their efforts. On July 14 Hay cabled Conger to use his good offices on behalf of the company and to protect American rights, but he also warned against doing wrong to China.68 Whether Hay was more concerned to push American business or to promote American prestige and influence in China, his instruction indicates that he did 67William R. Braisted, ”The United States and the American China Development Company,” Far Eastern Quarterly vol. XI (February, 1952). p. 150. See also pp. 147-48. 68Braisted, p. 152. 117 not want to violate Chinese sovereignty but saw no conflict between proper business agreements and China's administrative integrity. The supplementary agreement was reached in July, 1900, without the extra concessions the company had asked for. There were rumors at the time, later proved true. that the Belgians had gained a large share in the company. although this foreign influence was contrary to the agreement with China. The State Department might have been alarmed by the fact that the company's officials refused to answer China's questions about the rumor, and Conger reported that it was "generally understood" in Peking that Belgian and other Europeans held a portion of the company's stock.69 Conger was assured by the company's officials, however, that the company was still in American hands. William Barclay Parsons reported to Hay in December, 1901, that the company had been reorganized with himself as president, and listed the directors who included a number of foreigners. The Chinese again complained of violations of the contract. but Hay and Conger continued to support the company . 69Braisted, p. 154. 118 By January 21, 1904, the Chinese insisted that Belgium had complete control of the company, and Conger called the activities of the company "outrageous" and likely to bring "great discredit" on America.70 Parsons still insisted that the company was directed by Americans. In March General Whittier, who was regarded by the Chinese as a tool of the Belgians, was elected president. In May Hay told the Chinese Minister in Washington that the American government still supported the company and claimed the sole right to deal with diplomatic problems affecting the company, although he reserved the right to withdraw support should its conduct or organization be changed. Again Hay's reasons for continued support are not clear. It seems inconceivable that if his sole interest was in promoting American business that he would regard supporting dishonest business as the best means of gaining his end. Perhaps there was an element of American prestige involved. To back down at such a late stage would be to confess dishonesty, although Hay did later withdraw support. Hay probably did not trust the Chinese reports in the face of the company's denial of foreign influence; and the fact that he reserved the right to withdraw support may have indicated suspicions 7OBraisted, pp. 154-55. 119 on his part. It must also be remembered that Hay was frequently ill in his later years in office, and in any case he hated routine, so that he may not have paid sufficient attention to the affairs of the American China Development Company. When Parsons finally confessed in July, 1904, that Belgium actually did have a controlling interest, that "Leopold II failed to distinguish between good business practices and royal prerogative," and sought the State Department's help in regaining the Belgian shares, the State Department put pressure on the Belgians to sell by threatening to withdraw support from the company. When the company appealed again for help against Chinese obstructions in October, Hay told Conger to cease support and let the company and the Chinese work out their own disagreement. All work on the line ceased in October, 1904, after only ten miles had been built.71 Thus Hay, belatedly, did withdraw support from the American China Development Company when he became convinced that it had broken its contract by admitting Belgian interests. When in January, 1905, Hay learned that J. P. Morgan had succeeded in buying back enough Belgian shares to give 71Braisted, pp. 156-57. 120 American stockholders a majority, he again backed the company. But the Chinese, in the face of strong protests from the two provinces through which the road was to run, had determined to end the concession, and in May negotiations began between representatives of the company and the Chinese Minister in Washington for cancellation of the contract and to compensate the company for its losses. Compensation was set at the excessively high figure of $6,750,000. The 0 administration was understandably concerned about the damage this would do to America's reputation in China.72 Hay had by this time left the State Department in his final illness, and the problem of the American China Development Company fell to Roosevelt and Rockhill. Roosevelt was already concerned in Far Eastern Affairs through the Russo-Japanese peace negotiations, and Rockhill had just taken up his post as Minister to Peking. In their minds American prestige was definitely involved. Rockhill wanted the government to prevent the company selling out at such a usurious price, but he admitted that the Chinese had entirely lost confidence in the company as it was then 72Braisted, pp. 158-59. See also Consular Reports, Shanghai, vol. 50, Nos. 570, 588, for reports of the protests in Hunan and Hupeh provinces. 121 established. He thought the best solution was a reorgani- zation of the company. Roosevelt's reaction to the situation was complicated by his irritation at the Chinese for the manner in which they chose to handle the situation. They denied in Peking an intention to cancel the contract while negotiating in Washington for the sale of the company's rights. Roosevelt wanted to keep the company in business to teach the Chinese a lesson and uphold American prestige. He gave his frank View of the affair a few months later to Whitelaw Reid who had sent him some press clippings on the Hankow—Canton railway. The clippings . . . are not entirely fair to our people. The original American management is to be condemned because it finally did permit the road to be absorbed by the Belgians; but under the management of Pierpont Morgan enough stock was purchased to give the Americans control. The Chinese behaved in their usual manner. the local Viceroy inSisting that the Americans must sell. while the central government made tearful complaints about the Americans trying to extort so much money from them. I found out that one amount specified had been offered by the Chinese Minister himself and was only accepted by the Americans on the Chinese Minister's statement that the concession had already been revdked. The Americans were ready to go ahead on China's terms, he continued, but the Chinese stood firm. He then implied a 73Braisted, p. 161; Varg, pp. 93—96. 122 criticism of Hay's management of the affair. . . . if I had been in closer touch with the workings of the State Department than was the case until I had been some years in office, I should have taken drastic action long ago, both against the American members of this corporation who had sold out to the Belgians, and against the Chinese government.74 If Roosevelt had been interested only in furthering American economic interests in China. he would surely have accepted an offer by the Chinese for a railway loan in Manchuria in compensation for the loss of the Hankow-Canton . 75 railway. In vain did Roosevelt urge Morgan not to sell the company to the Chinese.76 Morgan and the stockholders were not prepared to continue even with government backing. Thus in this case the government was in the position of urging the financiers into a project they did not want. The reluctance of American financiers to undertake projects in China was further demonstrated by the fact that at this time the British and French were undertaking a loan for the Hankow-Chungking railway, and asked if the United States wanted to take up its option and join the loan. The 74Roosevelt Letters. V. pp. 29-30. 7SBeale, p. 209. 76For Roosevelt's letters to Morgan, see Roosevelt Letters, IV, pp. 1277-79, 1303. 123 State Department advertised the opportunity but found no interest.77 Whatever the attitude of the American government toward the American China Development Company while it was in existence. after its demise American officials seemed to regard it with nothing but distaste. Already in January, 1904, Conger had called the company a "great discredit” on the American government and people.78 In September of that year he reported that the Chinese intended to finance the Hankow—Chungking line themselves, but if they couldn't finance it they would seek money from Britain and America. Conger went on: I believe the Chinese government is sincere in its expressed desire to favor American enterprises of this kind, but the outrageous action of the American China Development Company with the Hankow-Canton line has largely destroyed the faith of the Chinese in our capitalists.79 The history of the American China Development Company provides on the surface a clear case of pressure by American 77Foreign Relations, 1909, pp. 147—48. 78Braisted, p. 155. 79Foreign Relations, 1909, p. 147. Other disparaging comments about the Company appear in Foreign Relations, 1909, p. 191; Consular Reports, Vol. 52, July 12, 1905, and September 25, 1905; Vol. 50, July 23, 1904, on the case of Boyd versus the American China Development Corporation. 124 financiers on the government to support their export of capital, and of government pressure on the Chinese government to uphold American business interests. This would clearly label the case one of imperialist activity within the Hobson-Lenin definition. However, there are enough unanswered questions about the transaction to raise some doubt that the case is so clear out. It is not enough to note the involvement of prominent financiers to prove the company was somehow disreputable, and that their major purpose was to export capital which could find no outlet at home. If this was the case. why was it necessary to seek Belgian capital to bolster the company? Why-did Morgan buy the Belgian shares only to sell the company a few months later? The motives of the American government do not necessarily support the theories of the economic interpretation of policy. While Hay was undoubtedly interested in supporting American business abroad, his primary consideration appears to have been to establish American prestige in China. Roosevelt was clearly motivated by questions of prestige plus a desire to ”teach China a lesson." By 1905, when Roosevelt was urging the company to stay on, it was clearly not a good business proposition, for not only Morgan and the stockholders wanted to sell out. but were advised to do so by Elihu Root who was legal adviser to the company. The 125 government may well have had in mind wider problems of a political nature. China needed capital. Should the American China Development Corporation give up the concession, it would probably fall to the Belgians or the British, a contingency the Chinese had all along been afraid of. In fact, the option did fall to the British. Certainly this case points up a whole range of questions concerning inter- national business relations which the economic historians tend to overlook. The questions were again posed by the international banking consortium of later years. If a country wants to encourage economic development, it must have capital. This then raised the problem of whether the money should be borrowed from an individual state, and if so, which state. or from an international consortium. China usually chose to borrow from individual countries, balancing her requests and playing the nations off against each other. Having selected the nation to borrow from, there was little choice but to borrow from private sources since governments did not make a practice of granting loans for commercial purposes. This, in turn, raised a whole series of problems concerning the relation of the lending company to its own government. Should the government of the lending power stay strictly out of the business affairs of its nationals; should it support its efforts only when it got into trouble; 126 or should it supervise the loan from its inception? None of these solutions to this last problem.was adopted by the American government with any consistency, and none was found to be entirely satisfactory. During the years in which John Hay was in charge of American policy in the Far East, America began to take a more active role in world affairs. It is maintained by the economic historians that this role was forced on the country by economic conditions, and that the Open Door Notes were designed to gain a share of the China market for America's surplus goods by keeping the open door for commercial enter- prises. A study of the origin of the notes and the subsequent diplomacy indicate that an additional and even more important consideration moved America to take a hand in Chinese affairs. This was the belief that the territorial and administrative integrity of China was important to protect America's political and strategic position in the Pacific. The Open Door Notes were framed with this object in View, in so far as existing conditions permitted. During the period of the Boxer Rebellion and the subsequent negotiations America used her limited force to prevent further weakening of the Chinese government. The limitation on America's ability to act was shown most forcibly by Russian encroachments in 127 Manchuria in 1901-03. Faced with Russian intransigence, Hay resorted again to commercial measures to uphold Chinese sovereignty in that region. Hay's policy was based on the assumption that legitimate trade was not incompatible with upholding the sovereignty of China, and that by enforcing freedom of trade and extending its scope, China could be strengthened. While in general this view is a reasonable one, it overlooked the peculiar conditions of China in which any move to strengthen the central government by the use of force from outside actually weakened it, and in which foreign business dealings almost inevitably became entangled with Great Power politics. Such a dilemma was well illustrated in the case of the American China Development Company. CHAPTER V THEODORE ROOSEVELT While Theodore Roosevelt was in the White House, he kept a strong hand on foreign affairs, and in the Far East he became the main policy maker after 1904. Although he kept within the framework laid down by Hay, there was a notable change of emphasis. Japan, not China, became the center of interest. In part this was due to Roosevelt's own temperament and his ideological concepts, and in part to the changed circumstances brought about by Japan's rise to power. Roosevelt's ideas about Japan fitted into his wider ideological views of the world, which were akin to those of Henry and Brooks Adams, Spring Rice and Mahan. There was the difference that Roosevelt was exuberant and optimistic whereas both the Adams brothers and sometimes Spring Rice tended to pessimism. Roosevelt also felt that the individual could make an impact upon events, although he realized that the individual was limited by given facts. Much of Roosevelt's policy was determined by his own moral outlook and his personal reactiontn individuals. He liked and trusted the German ambassador Speck von Sternburg. and the 128 129 English diplomat Cecil Spring Rice; he had no respect for the English Ambassador, Sir Mortimer Durand.l Similarly, he respected the Japanese and thought the Russians liars. This is not to say that his opinions of persons or events was necessarily wrong. His intuitions were often shrewd. But he regarded his own views of right and wrong as absolutes, and was not given to seeing the other side of the story. He was not a Social Darwinist in any such literal sense as Brooks Adams, but he did believe in struggle as a concomitant of life, and in power as the basis of survival. This stress on power often manifested itself in an almost farcical love of military or naval show, yet the President also knew what power was and did not believe in vain boasting or sabre-rattling. He also felt that power should not be exerted for its own sake and recognized its corrupting influence. It should be tempered by limitations of morality, law and duration.2 His letter to Hay on May 23, 1903, apropos of the Manchurian situation was typical. "I hate being in a position of seeming to bluster without 1Roosevelt was at his most colorful in describing Durand. ”He seems to have a brain of about eight—guinea— pig-power,” ”A creature of mutton-suet consistency,” he wrote. Roosevelt Letters, V, p. 242. 2Introduction to Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. xix-xx; Beale, pp. 449-54. 130 backing it up," he said.3 Similarly when the Jewish banker Jacob Schiff asked Roosevelt's intercession on behalf of the Jews in Russia, he replied that "where we can do nothing I have a horror of saying anything."4 He continually harped on the absurdity of the Californians who antagonized the Japanese with their racist legislation and refused to support a navy in case of conflict. Another facet of his concept about power was the belief that America should stand on her own feet and not trust to alliances. Only in this respect could America keep the respect of other nations. This, of course, accorded with the views of the country about entangling alliances.5 But while Roosevelt believed in power and strength as necessary to survival, his creed did not lead him to William Graham Sumner's conclusions about the merits of a laissez-faire economy. Though Roosevelt had no consistent philosophic view of man, he did believe that man had moral qualities that should be recognized. In domestic affairs government should act to insure justice to all men. In international affairs the "civilized” nations should police 3Roosevelt Letters, III, p. 428. 4Roosevelt Letters, V, p. 112. 5Roosevelt Letters, IV, pp. 1040—43, 1078—80. 131 the world. There were important qualifications to Roosevelt's acceptance of Social Darwinism. He did not accept the simple explanation that only the strongest nations would survive. Moral and intellectual strength were as important, in his View, as physical power. Nor did he accept war as a constructive process by which the weaker nations were eliminated.6 Nor did Roosevelt apply Social Darwinism in a racial sense. He was careful to point out that there was no such thing as an Aryan 'race,' only a language; that America and England were not destined to work together as members of an Anglo-Saxon race, because, in fact, America was a mixture of races: that Americans had more affinity to the Japanese than to the Russians, who were closer racially but who suffered from a despotic government. The essential element in world affairs to Roosevelt was a somewhat nebulous concept of ”civilization.” This was not precisely defined, but certain moral qualities appeared to be essential ingredients. Roosevelt was worried that civilizations would decline, as species did, but this decline would be as much moral as physical, and he was 6Introduction to Roosevelt Letters, V; Beale, p. 272. 7Roosevelt Letters. V, p. 723; IV, pp. 1040, 760. 132 continually feeling the nation's pulse to test its growth or decadence.8 In his opinion the most civilized nations were, with- out any doubt. America and Britain, and democratic institutions were the chief evidence of this quality. He was worried by signs of Britain's decline, and felt that America must help her in ruling the backward nations and in policing the world. Because of this sense of noblesse oblige, he approved Britain's rule over her empire and American rule in the Philippines. There was added to this reason for an expansionist policy a strain of pure patriotism which made him very sensitive about American prestige and honor abroad.9 Roosevelt greatly admired Japan because of that nation's readiness to adapt herself to the best in western civilization. That the process was only beginning in Japan troubled him less than the dogged adherence of the Russians to cumbersome and Vbarbaric' institutions. It was partly for this reason that he was glad to see Japan defeat the 8Roosevelt was influenced in these views by Brooks Adams' book, The Law of Civilization and Decay, with which he disagreed in detail yet felt was essentially true. His review of the book is reprinted from Forum of Jan. 1897 in The Works of Theodore Roosevelt, 24 Vols. Memorial Edition (New York, 1929), vol. XIV, p. 129 ff. 9Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. 16-17; Beale, pp. 3-22. 133 Russians. The Japanese had been truthful and honest in their yinternational dealings; they were efficient and hardworking; they were going ahead industrially; they were strong; they could rule themselves effectively; on the other hand the Russians were liars, they had a despotic government, they were inefficient. These were evidently the qualities that decided for Roosevelt whether a people were ”civilized” or "barbarian.” Nor did they necessarily have to conform to Western civilization in all respects. He admitted there were qualities the West could learn from Japan, and he did not seem to be concerned that Japan was not a Christian nation. He was evidently impressed with the Japanese statesmen he knew while he remained cool to the Russian Ambassador, Cassini, and though impressed by Serge Witte, he was shocked by his immorality.ll After Japan's victory in the Russian war, Roosevelt expressed his hope that Japan would take her place among civilized nations,12 whereby he seemed to imply that Japan should take responsibility for world peace and stability; and he expressed the belief that Japan sought peace not only 10Roosevelt Letters, IV, pp. 1221-33. 11Roosevelt Letters, V, p. 61. 12Roosevelt Letters, IV, pp. 829, 1233-34. 134 because she was exhausted or had no more to gain from war but because she wanted peace for its own sake.13 Roosevelt's enthusiasm for Japan reached its height with her naval victories over Russia, and so great was his love of a good fight that his enthusiasm temporarily over- came his caution. There was a good deal more warmth in his letter of congratulation to Baron Kaneko of May 31, 1905, than was perhaps seemly from the head of a neutral nation.l4 But on the whole Roosevelt did not lose a sense of proportion about Japan. As early as 1897 he wrote to Mahan that we ought to take Hawaii because of the dangers from Japan.15 In 1905 Japan was still an unknown quantity in international relations and Roosevelt believed it would be well for America to be on her guard. He recognized the danger of Japan's developing a "big head,"16 and saw symptoms of this in her insistence on an indemnity from Russia and l3Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. 58,61. l4Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 1198. In a similar mood he wrote to Spring Rice, "What a wonderful people the Japanese are . . . . They are quite as remarkable industrially as in warfare. In a dozen years the English. Americans and Germans . . . will have each to dread the Japanese more than they do any other nations." V, p. 1233. 15Roosevelt Letters, I, May 3, 1897. 16Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 829. 135 the anti-American riots in Tdkyo after the Treaty of Portsmouth was announced. As troubles with Japan over the California immigration question continued to plague America, he con- tinually stressed the necessity of national preparedness, and he discovered from the W. L. Madkenzie King, the Canadian politician, that the Japanese Government too was not above deceit in granting passports to laborers despite the Gentleman's Agreement.l7 Despite his reservations about Japan, Roosevelt's admiration for Japanese strength and efficiency led him to take a greater interest in America's relations with Japan than in her relations with China. While theoretically up- holding the open door and the territorial integrity of China, he did not have a strong personal interest in things Chinese. There are no references in his correspondence to Chinese friends, as there are to Japanese; he often felt irritation at Chinese inefficiency and weakness; he did not talk about Chinese Vcivilization' although he was well informed about Chinese culture by Rockhill and others.18 In fact Roosevelt barely mentions China in his letters. This personal bias toward the Japanese may explain why Roosevelt l7Roosevelt Letters, VI, pp. 918—21. 18Beale, pp. 180-81. 136 was slow to recognize their threat to American interests in Manchuria, even though two of our representatives in Tokyo, Lloyd Griscom and F. M. Huntington Wilson, were very suspicious of the Japanese. While Roosevelt's views on Japan fitted his ideological view of the world as a system of competing civilizations, they were tempered by the practical side of his nature. Despite his ideological concept of the world, Roosevelt did not have any detailed policy based on this ideology, but reacted to situations as they arose. As a recent commentator has put it: 'When in foreign affairs as in domestic the critical situation arose--as in Cuba, Algeciras, and Korea--there would be time enough to devise within our scheme of moral and practical considerations a specific solution to fit the particular occasion."19 An American pragmatism offset any tendency to create a make-believe world. Roosevelt's very belief that America should play a larger role in world affairs was a recognition of the fact that, as Mahan pointed out, the world was smaller since the introduction of steam power. The development of modern industry and communications was going to force America into a role she had heretofore escaped. Moreover, Roosevelt derived from BoOks Adams the 19Introduction to Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. xviii-xix. 137 idea that the center of power was shifting toward the Pacific, and that the Pacific would soon take on a new importance.20 It was a similar recognition of facts that made Roosevelt concerned with Japan. As the victor in 1905, Japan was a great power in the Pacific. With the Russian fleet destroyed, she had no naval rival in the Pacific area other than the United States. In the long term view the markets of China and possession of the Philippines might be the basic bone of contention between America and Japan, but in the immediate present the controversy over Japanese immigration to the West Coast focused attention on the danger of Japanese hostility on our very shores. What happened in China was of secondary importance compared to the apparent danger on our doorstep. While Roosevelt was probably never 2% afraid of war with Japan in 1907 a great many other people were, and he had to deal first with the problem at hand. Roosevelt always saw the Far East as the area where civilization and barbarism stood face to face. Japan and the United States represented the former, Russia the latter; and the China question was not one of markets but essentially one of maintaining a balance of power. ZOBeale. pp. 172, 174; Brooks Adams, pp. 72-77. 2J'Beale, p. 326. 138 Roosevelt did not reflect the contemporary concern about a market for surplus goods. In fact in one letter to Lodge he seems to discredit the notion that America needed to export surplus goods. Concerning complaints that American goods were being sold cheaper abroad than at home, he wrote: The fact is undoubted. It is of course due to the further fact that in every business the surplus is disposed of at below the regular prices. The popular way of expressing the fact is that the trusts sell goods lower abroad than at home, because of the way they are pampered by the tariff; yet the type example being used, for instance, is the price of a pair of American shoes in Kansas and in London respectively: and of course there is no shoe trust. This is a tariff question pure and simple, and has no relation whatever to the trusts. Yet I think it has a good deal of hold on the popular mind.22 Roosevelt's economic views were never very coherent,23 but the above quotation suggests that to his mind problems of surplus could be dealt with by tinkering with the tariff. Hobson and Lenin would probably have dismissed Roosevelt's arguments as mere camouflage for basic economic drives. Beard gave both McKinley and Roosevelt (but not Mahan) credit for sincerity in their ideological and moral views on world affairs. but felt they were mixed with material interests. Material interests were involved to be 22Roosevelt Letters, III, p. 331. 23Henry F. Pringle, Theodore Roosevelt: A Biography (New York, 1956), pp. 290-92, 303-05. 139 sure, for no statesman anywhere would remain long in office who set off on Quixotic adventures. The question is: what were the material interests involved? Were they economic, political or strategic? It would have been highly uncharacteristic for the outspoken Roosevelt to have indulged in a conscious obscuring of the issues. Roosevelt himself was neither interested in personal gain nor was he under the influence of powerful capitalist entrepreneurs. He was influenced by the intellectual climate of his times, but as has been pointed out, the ideas that had the greatest impact on him were not those of an economic nature. Roosevelt certainly knew and was close to many of the great financiers and capitalists of his time. but none ranked among his closest intimates. He often wrote that money was of no interest to him, and he put greater value on men who were not money makers. As for these rich men, I can speak quite disinterestedly. They are not my friends and never have been. My tastes unfortunately were wholly alien from.those which I hope my sons will possess in sufficient quantity to make them able to do their part in the industrial world. The money maker pure and simple not merely has no attraction for me, but is so antipathetic that if I am to get on with him it is best that we should see each other as little as possible. The men and women who have been intimate with me since I have been in the White House are the same as those who were intimate with me before I came to the White House. They include artists and architects. and writers, philanthropists of the genuine kind, politicians who 140 possess ideals, and hard workers in the business world who, nevertheless, do take a proper interest in politics or in philanthropy . . . as well as in business; they include men I met in the mountains and the backwoods and on the ranches and plains.24 In short Roosevelt regarded businessmen as individuals. just as he did labor leaders and Negroes. He refused to classify people in pat economic categories, and it was always the non- economic aspect of a man that appealed to him. As a group, Roosevelt said, ”an oligarchy of colossal capitalism is the most narrow-minded and meanest in its ideals.”25 In many cases Roosevelt even found business interests a handicap to the pursuit of the policy he desired. He wrote Spring Rice: Both your government and ours must reckon with the possible clamor the great business interests who regard everything that will tend to ”unsettle values/' as they call it, with unaffected horror, as being worse than any possible future national loss or even disgrace; and we also have to reckon with a funda— mentally sound, but often temporarily unstable or mistaken, public opinion,[as well as the peace—at- any price mentality.]26 This is in line with Mahan's characterization of the commercial classes as tending toward pacificism. Mahan had noted that it was the landed aristocracy who had built 24Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. 266—67. 25Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 1083. 26Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 1085. 141 England's sea power. Roosevelt's chief aides in determining policy in the Far East were Rockhill and Elihu Root, for whose ability as Secretary of State Roosevelt had great admiration. He was a better administrator than Hay and dealt more effectively with Congress. In the Far East Roosevelt laid down the policy and Root carried it out. but he always had the ear of the President and frequently changed the tone if not the meaning of the President's policy. In outlook as in age, Root was closer to Roosevelt than Hay had been. He shared Roosevelt's admiration for the Japanese and his irritation with, though not his contempt, for the Chinese.28 By the time of the Washington conference, when Japan had clearly shown her hand in China, Root was still sympathetic to Japan and felt that the aggressive forces had gained the upper hand because Japan had been thwarted by the Powers who were sentimental about China.29 While this may not be an accurate reflection of his feelings in 1905, it does indicate a bias toward Japan and a sense of working on the basis of the 7Mahan, Influence of Sea Power, pp. 66-68. 28Philip C. Jessup, Elihu Root, 2 Vols. (New York, 1938), II, p. 44. 29Jessup, II, p. 458. 142 power realities of the Far East. Japan was strong, China was hopelessly weak, and it was futile to go too far in thwarting Japan; particularly since Root was well aware from the beginning that the United States would never go to war to uphold the Open Door in China.30 Since this was the case, the United States had to remain on friendly terms with Japan while upholding its own strength. Those who interpret events from the economic point of View make much of the fact that Root was a corporation lawyer, had been counsel for the American China Development Company, and was in general connected with the interests of big business before he entered the State Department. This is another case of making the assumption that a man's thinking is all of one piece. One could make an equally strong case that Root's whole approach was legalistic. His biographer noted that his replies to China on the boycott question read like a legal brief and that he was criticized for being too legalistic in his handling of the problem of the Chinese Eastern Railway at the Washington Conference.3l As a lawyer he felt it his duty to give the best advice he could to his client--and in the Northern Securities case it was a 3OJessup, II, p. 452. 31Jessup, II, pp. 50, 458. 143 matter of sheer chance which side he did represent, as he was sought by both. So it was that he advised Morgan to sell the American China Development Company to China when Roosevelt was trying to prevent the sale. Despite his services to big business, he favored Roosevelt's trust busting activities and he carefully divested himself of all conflicting interests in business when he entered the War Department. Government became his chief client, and one he regarded as superior to private business. He did not believe in active government support of business enterprises abroad.32 It would, therefore, be difficult to say that Root was under the influence of wall Street in foreign affairs. (As for Roosevelt, his policy in the Far East was apparently shaped by ideological considerations and certain personal biases, and was little concerned with economic factors. Nor was he unduly influenced to act in the interests of big business and finance. iRoosevelt's few letters mentioning Far Eastern affairs before he entered the Presidency indicate that he was in agreement with Hay's policy of the Open Door, though he recognized the limitations of America's ability to support 32Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 1278; Jessup, II, pp. 54—55. 144 such a policy. He wrote Mahan expressing agreement on the whole with the views put forth in his book, Problems of Asia, but pointed out that the main problem was that public opinion was ”dull” on the subject of China, which from a world standpoint was more important than Alaska or the Canal about which opinion was more concerned.33 To Speck von Sternburg he wrote in October, 1901: I regard the Monroe Doctrine as being equivalent to the Open Door in South America. That is, I do not want the Uhited States or any European power to get territorial possessions in South America but to let South America gradually develop its own lines, with an open door to all outside nations, save as the individual countries enter into individual treaties with one another . . . . I wish the same policy could be pursued in China.34 This indicates that the open door was clearly tied to territorial integrity in his mind. He evidently relied heavily on Rockhill for his views on China. In writing to congratulate Rockhill on his appointment as Commissioner to China in the summer of 1900, Roosevelt remarked that he had only foggy ideas about China and asked Rockhill what line he ought to take in the fall election campaign.35 When Roosevelt became President, he 33Roosevelt Letters, III, p. 23. 34 Roosevelt Letters, III, p. 172. 35Roosevelt Letters, II, p. 1359. 145 Sent Rockhill to China as Minister. For Roosevelt Russia was the real threat in the East at the turn of the century, although he had earlier been more favorably disposed toward Russia.36 He wrote to Spring Rice in 1899: I understand all that you feel about Russia and of course Asia is the very place America could least help you . . . . The steady ethnic growth of Russia in Asia as opposed to Great Britain's purely administrative and political growth does make the Asian problem look serious.37 One of the first problems in Asia facing Roosevelt as President was the encroachment of Russia in Manchuria following the Boxer Rebellion. Roosevelt immediately sounded the note of ”Russian mendacity” which became his common theme by the time of the Japanese War. By 1903 he was expressing the wish that America could take a stronger hand in Manchuria but that American public opinion would not support such a policy.38 Although there was pressure from businessmen on the State Department and the American consuls in China to pry open the door in Manchuria, and Senator Lodge. sensitive to the cotton interests of Massachusetts, might have supported stronger measures, Roosevelt was well aware of 36Beale, p. 260. 37 Roosevelt Letters, II, pp. 1051-52. 38Roosevelt Letters, III, pp. 478, 532. 146 the lack of interest in the general public. Roosevelt's real entry into Far Eastern affairs came with the Russo-Japanese war. America's policy was two- fold; to uphold the neutrality of China; and to bring the war to a quidk conclusion before either side was exhausted. At the outset of war America, at the instigation of Germany, sent a circular note to the belligerents and the neutral powers urging that China's neutrality be maintained. Germany wanted to exclude Manchuria from.the area of China which was to be preserved, but Rookhill with Roosevelt's approval, reworded the notes to include Manchuria. Again in January, 1905, America urged the neutral powers not to gain concessions from China as the price of making peace between Japan and Russia. This was in response to German information that Britain and France had such designs.39 On several occasions during the war America protested to Russia and Japan on the violation of Chinese neutrality. The United States also continually impressed on the Chinese Government the necessity of enforcing neutrality itself. The United States insisted that if any American property in China should be damaged by the belligerents it would 39Griswold, pp. 93, 102-03; Roosevelt Letters, VI, p. 1497; IV, p. 731; Varg, p. 58. 147 hold the Chinese government responsible.4O While this might seem like the move of a grasping imperial power taking advantage of the weakness of China, it was in line with American policy during the Boxer Rebellion and later during the Boycott of insisting that the Chinese government take responsibility for its internal affairs. This line was also dictated by the fact that Roosevelt was not prepared to commit himself in advance to the preservation of China's neutrality by force. He wrote Hay on August 22 that the United States should not commit itself one way or another should Russia's ships violate Chinese neutrality, and again on August 24 he wrote Adee to tell the navy not to interfere if Russia and Japan should come to blows in Chinese ports until it had positive orders to do so. The same day he wrote to Hay that in this last contingency, the best solution would be for China to declare her inability to keep peace, and then let the beDigerents fight it out. In that way Russia could not use Chinese ports as havens, which she had been doing. At the same time Roosevelt was apparently prepared to fight if American ships should be seized by Russia for 41 I I I O contraband. Thus Roosevelt was anXious to maintain Chinese 40Foreign Relations, 1905, pp. 136-37, 140-41. 41Roosevelt Letters, IV, pp. 901, 903, 904, 869. 148 neutrality short of war, and he was prepared to fight only if specific American interests were at stake. He was not going to commit the country to a policy which he could not enforce. Roosevelt's role in bringing Japan and Russia together, and in the negotiations leading to the Treaty of Portsmouth is well known. What were Roosevelt's aims in these negotiations and what did the Treaty mean for American policy? Roosevelt was undoubtedly genuinely anxious to make peace for its own sake, and to enhance American prestige by being the mediating force. There was probably also an element of personal vanity. He wrote to Root on September 14: For the last six months most of what I have done in connection with foreign affairs, including the eastern war, Santa Domingo, Morocco, even venezuela, not to speak of the Hague conference--has been on an exclusively altruistic basis and I do not want people to get the idea that I never consider American interests at all, or still worse that I am posing as never considering them.42 “Roosevelt considered peace very much in the American interest before Japan Should permanently crush Russia in the East. He had in fact already several times urged Russia to make peace. ”While for the rest of us, while Russia's 42Roosevelt Letters, V, p. 26. 149 triumph would have been a blow to civilization, her destruction as an easte Asiatic power would also in my opinion be unfortunate.rfiLt is best that she be left fact to face with Japan so each may have a moderating action on the other.”43 So long as Japan remained interested in Korea, Manchuria and China, Russia would be her natural enemy, Roosevelt wrote Spring Rice. If Japan should shift her interests to other parts of the Pacific, she could be checked by sea power, whereas Russia was not vulnerable to sea power.44 With Roosevelt it was always axiomatic that America should maintain her sea power. ”While Russia and Japan would check each other in the Far East, he did not think the United States should trust either to an alliance or to the power position of other countries to safeguard her interests, but that she whould rely on her own efforts.45 These comments indicate that Roosevelt was thinking of the power position in the East in terms of protecting American interests in the Pacific rather than as a guarantee of China. >China would have been glad to see Russia and Japan wear each other out, as he was aware. 43Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 1230. 44 Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 1087. 45Roosevelt Letters, IV, pp. 1087, 1234. 150 England, too, he suspected, would like to see the war go on, and with this in View had urged the Japanese to demand an indemnity. Roosevelt tried to urge upon Britain the view that her interests would best be served if Russia were left with a position in Asia, for then she would have something to lose in future conflict, whereas if Russia were driven out of Asia, all possible damage would be done in that quarter and Russia would turn toward India or the Middle East, the areas in which Britain was most concerned. ‘It is apparent that Roosevelt did not consider Japan a threat to the United States in 1905. 1A year later, however, he stressed the importance of Russia as a cheek on Japan, and considered Russia no longer a threat in view of her internal troubles. Russia was also useful in drawing Japan's racial hostilities away fromAmerica.47 One of the results of the Russo-Japanese war was the establishment of Japan's protectorate over Korea, which America recognized in the Taft-Katsura agreement of July, 1905. This agreement has been represented by many writers as a sellout of China and an appeasement of Japanese imperialism to protect America's empire in the Philippines. The fact 46Roosevelt Letters, IV, pp. 1150, 1265-66. 47Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. 473-75. 151 that the Taft-Katsura talks were kept secret until 1924 added to the belief in a sinister meaning. This interpretation ignores several important points about the agreement. Although Japanese absorption of Korea was certainly an aggressive act, it cannot be regarded as an attack on the territorial integrity of China because by 1905 Korea had been recognized as an independent nation. Nor can this supposedly callous imperialist bargain have been brought about by pressures from economic interests because Roosevelt acted in the face of strong protests from.American business- men in Korea,48 and there is no evidence that rival business interests in the Philippines sought protection from Japanese attack. Roosevelt acted because he saw no hope of preventing Japanese aggrandizement in Korea which not even the Koreans xmere prepared to resist. It was a case of accepting the facts of power politics. Japan's special interest in Korea had already been recognized in the first Anglo-Japanese alliance, and was again in the renewed alliance, and it was also recognized in the Treaty of Portsmouth. Should America have wanted to oust the Japanese by force from Korea she 'would have had no help from Britain and might seriously have 48Beale. p. 316. 152 endangered her relations with that nation. American interests were not sufficiently great, Roosevelt felt, to risk conflict with Japan. “Apart from the limitations on action forced upon him by the Anglo-Japanese alliance and Japan's military position, however, Roosevelt actually seemed to feel that Korea was part of Japan's legitimate spoils of war. Remembering the troubles attendant upon depriving her of her spoils of war, in 1895, he felt America should see she was not robbed again.49 'he evidently long regarded Korea as a legitimate Japanese sphere, for at the time of the Boxer revolt he wrote that Japan'deserved” Korea for her role in rescuing the legations and checking the Russians. At that time, however, he feared that the Japanese acquisition of Korea would probably start another slicing of China which would be bad for everyone. Roosevelt probably also shared Root's belief that Japanese rule of Korea would be better than that of the opera bouffe Korean government.50 Although the Taft-Katsura talks were a recognition of a fait accompli and accorded with the recognition of 49Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 865. 50Roosevelt Letters, II, p. 1394; Jessup, II, p. 7. 153 Japan's position in the Treaty of Portsmouth which Roosevelt approved, the talks could not have been part of a deliberate plan because they were first sought by the Japanese and because Taft had no specific instructions from Roosevelt.51 There is also strong indication that the recognition of Japan's position in Korea was not granted in exchange for Japanese assurances concerning the Philippines and that the two sections of the agreement were not dependent upon each other. \Roosevelt did not believe Japan harboured any aggressive designs on China but genuinely believed in the open door.52'3His attitude of admiration for Japan, condescension for China and acceptance of facts in regard to Korea are revealed in a letter to Spring Rice long before anyone realized Japan would deliver a knockout blow to Russia and become a major Pacific power. He had lunched with the Japanese Minister and his friend Baron Kaneka, and told them he hoped Japan would not get a ”big head” by its victories. Of course they earnestly assure me that all talk of Japan's even thinking of the Philippines was nonsense. I told them that I was quite sure this was true . . . . I then said that as far as I was concerned I hoped to see China kept together and would gladly welcome any part played by Japan which would tend to bring 51Jessup, II, p. 5. 52Roosevelt Letters, IV, p. 1231. 154 China forward along the road which Japan trod, because I thought it for the interest of all the world that each part of the world should be prosperous and well policed; I added that unless everybody was mistaken in the Chinese character I thought they would have their hands full mastering it--at which they grinned and said that they were quite aware of the difficulty they were going to havesgven in Korea and were satisfied with that job. The separation of the Philippine and Korean question is seen in the above quotation. It is more explicit in Roosevelt's letter to Taft accepting Taft's agreement with Katsura. The statement about the Philippines was merely to clear up Japan's attitude, which had been purposely misrepresented by pro-Russian sympathizers and is shown [in Taft's memorandum] to have been entirely apart from your statements-- that is our statements--in reference to Korea and in reference to our having the same interests with Japan and Great Britain in preserving the peace of the Orient.54 ( (Roosevelt had some concrete reasons for his belief that Japan was no threat to the Philippines. In the first place Japan would be fully occupied with her prior interests on the mainland, and in the second place any attack on the Philippines would seriously strain her relations with England and bring on a coalition against her of the Uhited 53Roosevelt Letters, IV, pp. 829-30. 54Roosevelt Letters, V, p. 49. 155 States, Germany, France and Russia.55 The Taft—Katsura agreement has also been represented as a tacit joining of the Anglo-Japanese alliance. This is of course an exaggeration because the United States was never committed to act. Roosevelt approved of the Alliance and in some statements indicated that he would like to join, but in others he remarked on the weakness of England, and his own proclivities were against trusting to an alliance. He never seemed to realize the extent to which the British support of Japan worked against the interests of the Open Door in China, although he did complain that the British had refused to use their influence to get Japan to modify her demands at Portsmouth.56 The Root—Takahira agreement of 1908 is cited as further confirmation of the policy begun in 1905 to give Japan a free hand in Northern China in exchange for the security of the Philippines. There are ambiguities in the wording of the agreement that lend themselves to such an interpretation, but there is no contemporary evidence that Root or Roosevelt intended to appease Japan. The most 55Roosevelt Letters, V, p. 135. Again, however, Roosevelt added his axiomatic belief that America should keep her navy strong and should fortify the Sandwich Islands. 56Beale, pp. 171, 299, 305; Griswold, pp. 114-15. 156 ambiguous clause provided for the "maintenance of the existing status quo" in the Pacific region. However, this might be interpreted as a reference to the west Coast and Hawaii as well as to the Philippines. Other significant clauses promised to "respect the territorial possessions belonging to each other in said region,’ and reaffirmed their support "by all pacific means at their disposal the independence and integrity of China and the principle of equal opportunity for commerce and industry of all nations in that Empire." This last provision was a variation of the usual phrase calling for the preservation of "the territorial integrity and administrative entity of China,' and commentators have disagreed on whether it was a significant change. The omission of ”territorial” was not at the suggestion of the Japanese, however, and there is no indication that Root intended a different meaning. Because of the ambiguities of the language, the agreement cannot be properly understood except in the context of other events. Looked at in this way it fits into place as part of a policy that aimed at a careful balance of 57Williams, Diplomacy, p. 491; Jessup, pp. 36-37; Griswold, p. 129. Raymond A. Esthus, ”The Chancing Concept of the Open Door, 1899-1910,” Mississippi Valley Historical Review, Vol. 46 (Dec., 1959), pp. 445-49. 157 attitudes toward Japan. At a time when relations with Japan were tense, the United States sought to allay Japanese suspicions and antagonisms toward America while firmly upholding vital American interests. The Philippines were but one of these interests. The ambiguities were thus in part designed to blur the disagreements that did exist. lFrom the close of the Russo-Japanese war, American relations with Japan had deteriorated rapidly largely as a result of the immigration problem on the west Coast. This controversy reached war scare proportions by 1907, and while Roosevelt and Root apparently did not share the general alarm and Taft reported from Japan, which he visited in September 1907. that he did not believe the Japanese wanted war,?8 the situation was sufficiently inflammable to warrant preparedness. This preparedness included military measures not only in the Philippines but in Hawaii and on the United States' West Coast. Root, who did not expect immediate hostilities, feared a gradual drift to war.59 Roosevelt's attitude was consistent throughout. On one hand he urged the Californians to avoid irritating the 58Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. 527-29; VI, p. 946; Beale, p. 326; Jessup, II, pp. 26-27. 59Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. 730, 738, passim; VI, pp. 950—52, 937, passim; Jessup, II, pp. 25-26. 158 Japanese, and on the other hand, he, as always, urged the building of ships to deter a Japanese attack. Root followed the same policy toward California, While trying to reach an agreement with Japan on the immigration question.60 Similarly toward Japan the approach was twofold{ Roosevelt was anxious to show friendliness on minor issues, such as participating in a proposed international exposition in Tokyo,61 but at the same time he made it clear that America would remain firm on the immigration question. The fleet was sent on a world cruise with this as one of the purposes. The war scare subsided after the Gentleman's Agreement concerning Japanese immigration was reached at in the winter of 1907—08, but relations remained tense and it remained to be seen whether the Agreement would work. The first suggestion for a declaration of friendly intentions in the Pacific by the United States and Japan came from the Japanese Ambassador Aoki in October, 1907, but the idea was dropped at that time by the Japanese Foreign Office. With the friendlier atmosphere of 1908 and the change of government in Japan in July, the new Japanese Ambassador in Washington revived the idea. The Americans were anxious 60Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. 90-91; passim; Jessup, II. pp. 7-30. 61 Roosevelt Letters, VI, p. 964. 159 to foster the improved relations that had come about.62 That Root did not intend to give Japan a free hand in Manchuria is supported by the fact that during the year 1908 he had been protesting to the Russian Government con- cerning their encroaChments on the municipal government at Harbin on the legal basis of their railroad agreement with China of 1896. The United States did not want the Japanese to have such a precedent for using their railway rights in Southern Manchuria to extend administrative control there.63 It seems likely that Root was not fully alive to Japanese intentions on Manchuria despite Willard Straight's warnings, but believed they still followed the open door policy. The whole concept of the Gentleman's Agreement indicated an underlying faith in the good intentions of the Japanese government.64 Although the British welcomed the Root-Takahira agreement which lessened the tensions between their ally and their close friend, the British Ambassador Lord Bryce pointed out the unusual procedure of an outgoing administration reaching an agreement that could have no binding effect on 62Jessup, II, pp. 34—36. 63Foreign Relations, 1910, pp. 202-08. Esthus, pp. 445-49; Jessup, II, pp. 52-53. 64 Jessup, II, pp. 7, 29, 34, 37, 40—41, 44. 160 a new administration. The agreement was not a formal treaty.65 However well intentioned Root was, the ineptitude of his agreement had disastrous effects in China. The Japanese were able to represent the agreement to the Chinese as a Japanese-American rapprochement, and engineer the fall in January, 1909, of Yuan Shih Kai, who was strongly anti- Japanese. Root tried to rectify this move by protesting in vain against Yuan's dismissal.66 Yuan's fall was also due to the failure of Tang Shao Yi's mission to Washington to seek development funds for China. Although Root was sympathetic with the aims of this mission and permitted Tang's supporter, Willard Straight to introduce Tang to financial interests, he did not want to involve the State Department in financial dealings with China.67 This policy was advocated by Straight, who was at that time acting head of Far Eastern affairs in the State Department, and other members of the Department, and was adopted by the Taft administration. The Roosevelt administration was thus anxious to build up Chinese resistance to the Japanese by supporting 65John Gilbert Reid, The Manchu Abdication and the Powers, 1908-1912 (Berkeley, 1935). PP. 18-22. 66Varg, p. 80. 67Charles vevier, The United States and China 1906-1913: A Study of Finance and Diplomacy (New Brunswick, 1955). p. 78; Jessup, II, pp. 53-55. 161 YUan and encouraging investment, but it was not ready to involve the American government and American prestige directly in this effort. Relations with Japan were at such a dangerous point that in the view of the administration the support of China was a secondary consideration. This was indicated by the rejection of an alternative line of policy suggested by the German government. Late in 1907 the Germans suggested a new declaration of the open door in which China would participate. Yuan hoped to achieve such a declaration, but the Chinese were sufficiently dilatory to arouse Roosevelt's irritation, and in the end he rejected the proposal. Roosevelt told the German ambassador that he did not want to encourage excessive boldness in the Chinese for fear they would expect greater support from America and Germany than they would be prepared to give. The American people would accept a war with Japan over China only if vital American interests were at stake.68 Such vital interests were at stake in the immigration question, and to avoid war Japan had to be mollified. The Root-Takahira agreement was the rather inept method chosen. ( 'Throughout his term in office Roosevelt's Far Eastern policy hinged on relations with Japan rather than 68Reid, p. 22; Vevier, pp. 69, 74; Varg, p. 78. 162 with China, partly because events forced Japanese questions 2 to the fore. 1At the beginning of his term of office Japan was a relatively weak power, but one the President admired for its adjustment to western influence and later for its fighting skill. He believed that Japan deserved a place in the sun and should not be thwarted in its legitimate claims. He did not believe these claims were incompatible with the territorial and administrative integrity of China. At the end of the Russo-Japanese war he sought to maintain the balance of these two powers in the East, and welcomed the Anglo-Japanese alliances as a stabilizing force. JAfter the war Japan became a power in the Pacific and Roosevelt's policy shifted accordingly. As tempers rose over the immigration question, his attitude toward Japan stiffened, yet he tried to maintain a balance in order not to antagonize Japan. Both the Taft-Katsura agreement and the Root-Takahira agreement have to be interpreted in the context of the administration's total policy. This policy aimed at firmness where vital issues were concerned, and understanding on peripheral issues. It included the Gentleman's Agreement, the pressures on those in California responsible for anti-Japanese actions, naval preparations, the cruise of the fleet, the protests on Harbin. 163 During these later years of his term Roosevelt regarded the immigration problem as the central issue, not the Philippines, although on occasion he registered his concern about their security.69 Toward the end of his term he could speak of the Philippines as an Achilles heel. Our rule had benefited the islands, he believed, but he would have liked to see their independence as this would have removed temptation from the Japanese.70 That the Japanese problem worried Roosevelt was indicated by a letter he wrote the incoming Secretary of State in February, 1909. . . . There is one matter of foreign policy of such great and permanent importance that I wish to lay it before the President-to-be and yourself. I speak of the relations of the United States and Japan . . . . But with Japan the case is different [from other potential problems]. She is a most formidable military power. Her people have peculiar fighting capacity. They are very proud. very warlike, very sensitive, and are influenced by two contradictory feelings. namely, a great self- confidence, both ferocious and conceited, due to their victory over the mighty empire of Russia; and a great touchiness because they would like to be considered as on a full equality with, as one of the brotherhood of, Occidental nations, and have been bitterly humiliated to find that even their alfies, the English, and their friends, the Americans, won't admit them to association 69Roosevelt Letters, V, p. 473. 70Roosevelt Letters, V, pp. 776, 762. 164 and citizenship, as they admit the least advanced or most decadant European peoples. Moreover, Japan's population is increasing rapidly and demands an outlet, and the Japanese laborers, small farmers, and petty traders would, if permitted, flock by the hundred thousand into the United States, Canada and Australia. America could not permit such large scale immigration, Roosevelt continued, but in preventing this it was necessary to act with "all possible courtesy and consideration,” and to be "thoroughly armed, so as to prevent the Japanese from feeling safe in attacking us.” He went on, Moreover, Japan is vitally interested in China and on the Asiatic mainland and her wiser statesmen will if possible prevent her getting entangled in a war with us, because whatever its result it would hamper and possibly ruin Japan when she came to deal again with affairs in China. But with so proud and sensitive a people neither lack of money nor possible future complications will prevent a war if once they get sufficiently hurt and angry; and there is always danger of a mob outbreak there just as there is danger of a mob outbreak here.71 'iThe implication of this letter is that Japan should be given a free hand in Northern China in exchange for restricting her immigration to the United States, rather than for respecting American rule in the Philippines. However, Roosevelt probably did not intend to countenance 71Roosevelt Letters, VI, pp. 1510-14. 165 such flagrant abuses of Chinese sovereignty as did in fact take place. but hoped by the right policy to encourage the "wiser statesmen.” This idea is suggested in a letter to an English friend in which he says, "Indeed the agreement [of England] with Japan is an admirable thing all around. As you say it is a knockout for the mischief makers on both sides of the Atlantic--and I may add on both sides of the Pacific.”72 On all occasions Roosevelt tried to avoid committing the United States to a policy that the country would be unable to or unwilling to enforce. His dislike of ”blustering" was registered at the time of the Manchurian crisis in 1903. He still clung to the same theme in 1910 when a letter to Taft expressed his views on the policy of his successors. Although the statement may benefit by the clarity of hindsight, it is a fair summary of Roosevelt's outlook on Manchuria and Far Eastern affairs in general. . . . It is therefore peculiarly our interest not to take steps as regards Manchuria which will give 72Roosevelt Letters, VI, p. 1432. Beale argued that the sending of the fleet on the world cruise had the effect of helping the militarists to power in Japan, and that Roosevelt was totally unaware of the effect of American policy on internal Japanese affairs (p. 331). These letters suggest Roosevelt was not insensitive to Japanese feelings, although he perhaps misjudged the effect of his actions. 166 the Japanese cause to feel, with or without reason, that we are hostile to them, or a menace--in however slight a degree-—to their interests . . . I utterly disbelieve in the policy of bluff, in national and international no less than in private affairs, or in any violation of the old frontier maxim, "Never draw unless you mean to shoot." I do not believe in our taking any position anywhere unless we can make good; and as regards Manchuria, if the Japanese choose to follow a course of conduct to which we are adverse, we cannot stop it unless we are prepared to go to war, and a successful war about Manchuria would require a fleet as good as that of England, plus an army as good as that of Germany. The Open Door policy in China was an excellent thing, and I hope it will be a good thing in the future, so far as it can be maintained by general diplomatic agreement; but as has been proved by the whole history of Manchuria, alike under Russia and under Japan, the ”Open Door” policy, as a matter of fact, completely disappears as soon as a powerful nation determines to disregard it, and is willing to run the risk of war rather than forego its intention.73 Here the expansionist of 1898 is stating firmly that there is limit to America's interests and ability to control events in other parts of the world. 73Quoted in Reid, p. 182. CHAPTER VI TAFT, THE BANKERS AND CHINA At first glance William Howard Taft's Far Eastern policy appears to substantiate J. A. Hobson's interpretation of imperialism. Indeed a number of historians have so inter- preted it. These writers point an accusing finger at Taft's own use of the term ”dollar diplomacy,” they cite the pressure exerted to open the door to American capital in Manchuria, and they portray Willard Straight as the agent of interests who wished to make the government the handmaiden of finance capital. An examination of the facts suggests that this explanation is at best much too simple and at its worst borders on distortion. Taft and his Secretary of State, Philander C. Knox, took office at a time when the traditional open door policy with its emphasis on equality of commercial opportunity was becoming ineffective. The larger aim of that policy was a strong China and its concomitant, a balance of power in the Far East. By March, 1909, it was clear for all to see that China's integrity and independence was being compromised by Japan's aggressive use of her South Manchurian railroad to dominate the provinces north of Peking. And in the 167 168 northern half of Manchuria, Russia through her ownership of the Chinese Eastern Railway, was exercising sovereign powers that violated the territorial and administrative integrity of China. A new network of railroads in China proper to be financed by foreign powers suggested that in the future nations with a predominance of capital investment would dominate Chinese affairs and the influence of the United States would be destroyed. The dangers inherent in this foreign domination were increased by the fact that the Chinese government was going through a period of instability following the death of the Emperor and Empress Dowager in December, 1908.‘ Taft and Knox responded to the changing situation in China with a determination to revitalize America's traditional policy of preserving the territorial and administrative integrity of that country. The Taft administration soon sought to achieve its goals by applying the open door concept to investment as well as to commerce. There was a particular effort to introduce American capital into Manchuria through the Chinchow—Aigun railway plan, the Knox Neutralization Proposal and the Currency Reform Loan, but the principle was also applied to China proper in the effort to join the Hukuang loan. The new strategy was in part a natural response to what was taking place in Manchuria, but it 169 also had its origins in Edward Harriman's efforts to implement his dream of a globe—encircling transportation system. The American railway magnate took his first step to achieve this grandiose scheme on a trip to Japan in 1905 when he hoped to buy a share in the Southern Manchurian railway which Japan had just acquired from Russia by the Treaty of Portsmouth, an acquisition later confirmed by a secret agreement with China in December, 1905. Harriman was able to approach the Japanese through his connection with the bankers, Kuhn,Loeb and Company, who had lent money to Japan during the war, and through Lloyd C. Griscom, the American ambassador to Tokyo. Griscom favored supporting American business and acted on Harriman's behalf without prior consultation with Roosevelt, who had just brdken with Harriman over the Northern Securities case. Harriman actually reached an agreement with the Japanese, but it was soon repudiated when Baron Komura returned from Portsmouth.l While he was in the Far East, Harriman met Willard Straight, a young American who had just become vice-consul in Seoul. Straight developed a passionate hatred for the 1Lloyd C. Griscom, Diplomatically Speaking (Boston, 1940). pp. 263-64. 170 Japanese while watching them take over Korea. He became interested in Harriman's railway plan as a means to prevent further Japanese encroachment on the mainland of Asia. Harriman in turn saw a useful agent in Straight who was intelligent and well informed on Far Eastern affairs. A year after he met Harriman, Straight took up residence in Mukden as America's first Consul General. Here he devoted his efforts to promoting American business to offset the predominant influence of Japan.2 Throughout 1906 the Japanese, pleading military necessity, had hindered the entrance into Manchuria of foreign businessmen while allowing free entry to their own. At the same time that they were completing arrangements for their own government's control of the Southern Manchurian Railway, they were hindering the establishment of international settlements and the organization of the Chinese Customs in the Manchurian treaty ports.3 In June, 1906, three Shanghai businessmen, anxious to investigate the bottleneck for goods transshipped from Shanghai into Manchuria, reported that Japan seemed to be favoring her own merchants, although they could offer 2Croly, pp. 207—12, 235. 3Foreign Relations, 1906, pp. 170-72, 177-82, 195, 198—99, 202 passim. 171 no definite proof. Straight came to the conclusion that American trade simply could not be great enough under existing conditions to offset the Japanese, who could add military and political pressure to trading advantages. What was needed was more capital investment to increase the potential market for American goods.5 With Harriman's project in mind, Straight began to work with the Chinese in Manchuria to find a railway route that would offset the influence of the Southern Manchurian route but at the same time offer no valid excuse for Japanese objections.6 The plan then expanded into one for a loan to establish a Manchurian bank that would under- take the general development of the region. The plan for a railroad was sent to Harriman on August 7, 1907, but it arrived at a moment when the Panic of 1907 was in full swing 4Foreign Relations, 1906, p. 210; Consular Reports, Shanghai, Vol. 53, No. 170. The movement of American goods to Manchuria was considerably complicated at this time by the Chinese boycott, which affected Shanghai, the port from which goods were shipped into Manchuria. 5Croly, pp. 237-38; Vevier, p. 45. The precise route of the railroad changed during the course of negotiations, but the essential idea to parallel the South Manchurian remained the same. The first plan called for a road from Hsinmintun to Tsitsihar on the Chinese Eastern Railway. The final route ran from Chinchow to Aigun on the Russian border. 172 and Harriman could not raise the necessary funds.7 After this setback, Straight worked to convert the American government to his policy of introducing American capital into Manchuria, and he eventually succeeded. Thus any interpretation of American policy rests very largely on one's interpretation of the relationship between Straight and Harriman. Charles vevier thought Straight was merely an agent for Harriman, and he concluded that the China policy of the American government was really just a cover for Harriman's railway schemes.8 It seems more likely, however, that Straight saw in Harriman's plans a means to further his own efforts to prevent Japanese encroachment. This interpretation of Straight's motives is more in accord with the personality of Straight as portrayed by his friend and biographer, Herbert Croly.9 Far from being the typical agent of economic imperialism, Straight was a .complex mixture of idealist and selfseeker, artist and adventurer. Like his colleague Rockhill, he was a devoted student of Chinese civilization, and at the same time he ‘was a strong American patriot. His detractors usually fail 7Croly, pp. 240-42; Vevier, pp. 46—47. 8Vevier, pp. 215-17. 9This view is also taken by Straight's associate, F. M. Huntington Wilson, Memoirs of an Ex—diplomat (Boston 1945). p. 167. 173 to mention that he was the founder of one of America's most liberal journals, The New Republic. While he was an official of the Chinese Imperial Customs, he revealed his ambitions in his diary: But the Service will never be my life nor the success in the Service my aim. It will rather be to draw the Chinaman as he is or to write of him or to know him so well that some day I can put my finger in the ”international pie."lo Straight saw a role for himself as a pioneer, not in opening new territory in China, but in opening China to new commercial ventures. He was moved by a mixture of adventure, ambition and philanthropy. That Straight was not purely Harriman's tool is indicated by the fact that it was he who continually took the initiative for economic schemes in the Far East. He first made arrangements with Manchurian officials for a railway to parallel the Japanese-controlled Southern Manchurian line, then sent the plan to Harriman. After Harriman's death he continued to carry on negotiations for this plan independently. In 1909 he refused to go to China as the agent for Kuhn, Loeb and Company, Harriman's bankers, but did go as the representative of the American Group of 10Quoted in Croly. p. 116. See also p. 117. 174 bankers, which was the agent of the State Department. This suggests that it was a larger outlook, not just Harriman's railway venture, that interested him. Not long after the China venture ended, he resigned his post with J. P. Morgan and Company because business as such did not interest him, although he kept connections with other organizations involved in foreign trade.11 Critics of Straight overlook the fact that a policy similar to his was advocated by a large number of Chinese concerned with Manchurian affairs. In 1906 the governor of Heilungchiang, one of the Manchurian provinces, sent a memorial to the Imperial government advocating a Chinese- financed railway from Hsinmintun to Potuna, and in the following year there were suggestions for other railways in Manchuria. The Ministry of Communications in Peking recom- mended to the Grand Council the building of a Hsinmintun- Tsitsihar extension of the Peking-Mukden railway. In June of 1907 the Chinese administration of Manchuria was reorganized on a civilian basis to strengthen the local government against Japan and Russia. The new civilian governor general, Hsu Shih-Chang and the governor of Fengtien llCroly, pp. 459-61. 175 province, Tang Shai-yi, saw that foreign capital would be needed for any railways in Manchuria. On the basis of Chinese documents, Robert L. Iridk states that it was the Chinese who first approached Straight with the suggestion of building a Hsinmintun-Tsitsihar line.12 Tang and Straight made the agreement that was forwarded to Harriman in 1907. Throughout the ensuing negotiations the officials in Manchuria continually pressed the Peking government to make an agreement with the Americans, but the more conservative elements in Peking were less sure that America would honor its option in the face of Russian and Japanese objections, and many Chinese objected to foreign loans in general.13 Furthermore. Straight's critics do not explain why, if he were merely Harriman's agent, he supported the move to introduce French and British capital into Manchuria when Harriman was unable to supply the necessary funds. In November, 1907, Tang came to an agreement with the English railway financiers, Lord ffrench of Pauling and Company and J. O. P. Bland of the British and Chinese Corporation. Both Lord ffrench and Bland had hoped to swing British 12Robert L. Irick, ”The ChinchOWhAigun Railroad and the Knox Neutralization Plan in Ch'ing Diplomacy,” Papers on China, from the East Asia Regional Studies Program, Harvard University, Vol. 13 (Dec., 1959), pp. 83-84. 13Irick, pp. 105-06, passim. 176 policy away from support of Japan to support of her own commercial interests in Manchuria, and in this endeavor their interests were similar to Straight's. Their calculations failed. Japan opposed the concession on the basis of her secret agreement with China of December, 1905, that no railroad parallel to the Southern Manchurian would be built; and the British government refused to back Pauling and Company against their ally.l4 Although Straight was not successful in 1907 in introducing American capital into Manchuria, he had already begun work to gain support for his policy. After he had written Harriman, he informed the Assistant Secretary of State of his plan, but without mentioning his letter to Harriman. In November, 1907, he met Taft in Manchuria and discussed Far Eastern problems with him. In July Straight was called home, at Harriman's instigation, to negotiate further on the railway plan. The panic was receding and Straight hoped that Harriman would now finance the agreement he had reached with Tang if the American government 15 supported him. Tang himself also came to Washington, ostensibly to l4Croly, pp. 243-48; vevier, pp. 51-57. 15Croly, pp. 249-51, 266; Vevier, pp. 49, 59-62, 72. 177 thank the United States for its return of the Boxer indemnity, but in reality to discuss two plans. One was a variation of his own plan which called for the use of the funds remitted from the Boxer indemnity to establish a bank for the development of Manchuria. Straight approved this idea, but it was opposed by Rookhill and William Phillips, who wanted to use the Boxer funds for the education of Chinese in America, and who distrusted Chinese financial methods. Roosevelt too opposed the use of these funds for the Manchurian scheme because he did not want to antagonize the Japanese in Manchuria and felt that "we were in no position to have our bluff called.”l6 Moreover Tang arrived in Washington just as the Root-Takahira agreement was being signed. Straight did manage to get the State Department's approval, in Root's absence, to negotiate with Harriman for a Manchurian bank loan. Tang's other proposal--a loan for financial reforms in China proper which would presumably include capital from other powers--met with greater sympathy from the administration. for it was in accord with the policy America had followed since the Boxer protocol and the Treaty of 1903. Straight received Root's personal approval to introduce Tang into 16Quoted in Vevier, p. 75. 178 commercial circles for this purpose, with the warning that "the State Department had no wish or authority to involve the United States in any obligation either legal or moral with reference to such a loan."17 Straight was authorized to publish this View to anyone who was interested in the loan. Despite this disclaimer of government involvement, Harriman continued negotiations. The government's specific refusal to be associated in such a loan was in accord with the Roosevelt policy not to antagonize Japan, yet both Root and Roosevelt approved of financial reform in China. This proposal of Tang's was the basis for America's later involvement in the Currency Reform Loan. Straight brought both plans directly to Harriman. but the negotiations came to nothing. The death of the Empress Dowager and the Emperor put Tang's credentials in doubt, and the fall from power of Yuan Shih Kai, largely as a result of the Root-Takahira agreement, undermined Tang's political position. It should be noted that to the end of the Roosevelt regime the only railroad plan under discussion between China and America was the private negotiation of Harriman and Straight for the Chinchow-Aigun.18 17Quoted in Vevier, p. 78. 18Croly, p. 281. 179 Since he had arrived in Washington, Straight had been active in converting members of the State Department to his view, that American capital alone could prevent the further disintegration of China, and by the time the Taft administration took over his outlook was in the ascendant. Taft and Knox were in favor of a more active policy in China and a more active government role to support business. There was also a strong anti—Japanese bias. F. M. Huntington Wilson, who had become distrustful of the Japanese during his years in TOkyo, was Assistant Secretary of State.19 Rockhill, who had been more sanguine about Japan, was transferred from Peking to St. Petersburg. The first manifestation of the change in the attitude of the American government was the American effort to enter the Hukuang loan, and the formation in June, 1909, of the American Group of bankers. The new administration also was soon involved in Straight's plans in Manchuria. Straight resigned from the State Department to become the representative of the American Group in negotiations in London with the European bankers and later in Peking with the Chinese and foreign bankers for the Hukuang loan. He continued to lead 19Huntington Wilson, pp. 70-72, 86, 127, 145-50, passim. 180 a double life, with the Chinchow-Aigun plan as his secret mission. Harriman, who was one of the members of the American Group, asked Straight to continue negotiations with the Manchurian officials and also with the Russians for the sale of the Chinese Eastern railway. The Manchurian plan had received a new impetus in the winter of 1908 when a French banker, representing Russian interests, offered to sell the Chinese Eastern Railway to Jacob Schiff of Kuhn, Loeb. Schiff had rejected the plan because of his anti-Russian sentiments, but Harriman hoped to revive the connection. With the ChinchowaAigun concession, the Chinese Eastern, and trackage rights on the Trans-Siberian, the round-the world line envisaged by Harriman would be in sight. Straight calculated that with the Chinchow~Aigun concession and the Russian connections the Japanese would be forced either to sell the South Manchurian or see it eclipsed by the rival railway.20 The first necessary step was therefore a solid concession for the Chinchow-Aigun line and to this purpose Straight negotiated with Manchurian officials in the summer of 1909, after first pooling resources with Pauling and Company. On October 2 he made a preliminary agreement with the Manchurian officials, who exceeded their 20Vevier, pp. 82, 117—21; Croly, pp. 296-98. 181 orders in doing 50.21 There was no imperial edict to ratify the agreement until January, 1910. Straight's problem was complicated by the death of Harriman on September 10, 1909. The rest of the American Group were not informed of Harriman's plan except in the vaguest way until Straight wrote to inform them, but circumstances forced him to sign the October 2 agreement before he had definite authorization from the Group. Thus until the final signature, the Manchurian project remained the scheme of Harriman and Straight. The government was not involved, and the American Group's primary concern was the Hukuang loan.22 Straight was hopeful of completing the railway link, for J. O. P. Bland had returned from Russia in October and reported that Russia was ready to admit British and American capital into Siberia to build a line from Irkutsk to Kalgan.23 Straight had hoped to go to Russia to complete negotiations for this line and for the sale of the Chinese Eastern after he had gained approval from the American Group. Events intervened. 21Irick, p. 92. 22 . Croly, pp. 303-05; VeVier, pp. 126—131. 23Vevier, p. 132. 182 Once the preliminary agreement for the Chinchow- Aigun line was signed, the situation changed. The American Group, disgusted with the complications on the Hukuang loan, came to regard the Manchurian line as its primary interest, and it was hoped that this concession would strengthen America's hand in the Hukuang negotiations.24 It was at this point that the State Department entered the scene with the Knox Neutralization Proposal, and turned what on the surface had been a private business negotiation into a political project. Unfortunately for the Chinchow-Aigun plan, it was precisely its political implications that finally defeated it, whatever slim chance it might have had as a business venture. The Neutralization Proposal consisted of two alter- natives. The first was a loan by the interested powers to China to buy the railways (and highways) in Manchuria. If this failed, the other alternative was for Britain and America, whose nationals held the Chinchow-Aigun concession, to support this concession and invite the other interested powers to join the financing of the Chinchow-Aigun line and any future railways in Manchuria.25 Knox proposed 24Vevier, p. 137; Croly, p. 301. 25Williams, ed. Diplomacy, p. 492. 183 neutralization as the first alternative because his primary purpose was to eliminate the Russian and Japanese spheres of influence in Manchuria. Under this plan the American Group would have had a less prominent role than under the second proposal. The suggestion for supporting the Chinchowe Aigun railway was made to create a threat to Japan and Russia, and force them into supporting the neutralization scheme. The Knox Neutralization Proposal was based on Straight's line of thinking, but there seems to have been no specific consultation between the State Department and Straight, who was in China, before it was put forth. Straight had not consulted the Department on his negotiations with the Manchurian officials, although he had informed them. He at first approved the Knox proposal; later he became very critical of its handling, particularly the snub to Russia. It had become one of Straight's cardinal beliefs that Russia must be placated and even admitted to the Hukuang and Manchurian loans. The fact that Knox directed his proposal against Russia is one indication that Straight had not been consulted.26 Straight was also critical that the plan was published before the Imperial edict ratifying the ChinchoweAigun 26Vevier, pp. 136, 138, 142-43; Croly, pp. 308-09. 184 railway agreement had been published, as this weakened America's position abroad and undermined her good faith with China.27 It is not clear from Vevier's account what communi- cation there was between Knox and the bankers concerning the Neutralization Proposal. Jacob Schiff of Kuhn, Loeb denied any prior knowledge; Henry P. Davison, of J. P. Morgan, said the American Group had been informed in late October of the plan, but this does not necessarily mean that there had been consultation. Vevier cites a State Department dispatch to the Embassy in Tdkyo as evidence that "American bankers had requested support for the Chinchow-Aigun line,”28 but this in no way implies a request for an international proposal such as the Knox plan. It would certainly be strange if businessmen, who had just reached a preliminary agreement with the Manchurian officials for a profitable concession and had strong hopes of concluding an agreement 7Knox had issued the Neutralization Proposal on the basis of unofficial information received by Straight that the edict had been promulgated (vevier, p. 141); but this was not sound enough as the basis for an international proposal. As late as December Straight and Henry P. Fletcher, the American Charge d'Affaires in Peking, were still specu- lating on whether the edict had been issued, which Fletcher doubted (Irick, p. 99). In fact it did not come until January, 1910. 28Vevier, pp. 141, 149-50. 185 with Russia, would want to upset negotiations at that point. It is more reasonable to suppose that the Knox plan was the outcome of a separate line of reasoning. Knox moved into the political arena precisely because there were political considerations that not only threatened the success of the Chinchow-Aigun project but the political balance in the Far East and the integrity of China. These threats came from two directions. In May, 1909, the Russians reached an agreement with China concerning the administration in Harbin. The United States found this Sino-Russian agreement unacceptable, and relations with Russia remained strained throughout the summer.29 A note verbale to Russia dated November 6, 1909, even hinted at an offer to Russia to join the Hukuang loan if she would recognize the open door in Harbin.3O This was in accord with the views of Straight, who had argued that Russia's sale of the Chinese Eastern Railroad would end the dispute over Harbin by removing the legal basis on which she claimed administrative rights in the city. This argument was accepted in the State Department.31 Knox, however, instead of letting 29Foreign Relationstl910, pp. 208-17. 30Foreign Relations, 1910, pp. 218-20. 31Foreign Relations, 1910, pp. 225-26. 186 the dispute over Russian rights in Harbin lie dormant while he discussed the Neutralization Proposal with Russia, con- tinued to press the matter, and by so doing irritated Isvolsky, the Russian Foreign Minister. Knox's insistence on the American position over Harbin, blunder that it was, suggests that the political principle involved there was more important to him than the conclusion of a private business agreement in Manchuria. In addition to the Russian moves in Harbin, China's sovereignty in Manchuria, already deeply compromised by Japan, was further threatened in September by a new Sino—Japanese agreement concerning railways and mines.32 Japan was also threatening to protest to her ally Britain against China's concession of the ChinchowaAigun line, as she had done successfully in 1907.33 Moreover a proposed meeting between the Japanese statesman, Prince Ito, and the Russian Finance Minister, deovtsov, which never took place because of the assassination of Ito, had produced rumors of a Japanese offer to buy the Chinese Eastern Railway to prevent its sale to America or China.34 Ito had long favored a Russo-Japanese 2 Foreign Relations, 1909, pp. 116-20. 33Vevier, p. 138. 34 . . VeVier, pp. 144-45; Irick, pp. 94, 97. Fletcher had cabled a warning about the Ito-KOkovstov meeting to the State Department Oct. 30 (Varg, p. 103). 187 rapprochement, but Kokovtsov was supposed to favor the sale of the Chinese Eastern to the Harriman interests. Rumors of the sale of this railway to the Japanese were upsetting to the Americans because a further drawing together of Japan and Russia would put an end to Chinese sovereignty as well as American commerce in Manchuria. On top of this worry, there were secret troop movements in Manchuria by both Japan and Russia.35 Although the Manchurian officials had favored some form of international loans to Manchuria to offset Russian and Japanese influence and had signed an agreement with Straight, Peking was cautious and had no intention of ratifying the agreement until there was official American support to add political strength to economic. In any case Peking officials on the whole preferred a general loan for Manchuria to join; control of the railroad as envisaged by the Straight plan. Although the American Charge d'Affaires, Henry P. Fletcher, knew of this preference by NOvember 6,36 Washington probably was not aware of it before the Knox plan was sent to Britain. All commentators seem to agree that Knox badly mismanaged the negotiations for implementing his plan, 35Irick, p. 96. 361rick. pp. 95-96. 188 especially those with Russia, but it is doubtful in View of the international situation that he could have succeeded with the most skillful diplomacy. The parallel of the plan with the Open Door Notes is notable.37 In this case a part of China, Manchuria, was threatened with partition. and in the hopes of preserving Chinese sovereignty Knox hoped to inject American financial interests to keep the door open. Knox even admitted that the plan was ”somewhat ideal,"38 but he may have hoped to pull some such coup as Hay had managed with the Open Door Notes. As in 1899, America was not prepared to support the plan with any kind of military or political commitment to China or the other powers, although it was hoped that financial power would provide a substitute. The situation in 1909 differed from 1899, however. In the first place a specific American financial interest was at stake instead of a general interest in trade. More important, the alignment of European Powers had shifted and the lines of antagonism had sharpened. America had barely a potential ally in her efforts. as . . . . . 39 Britain's cool reception of the Knox plan indicated. 37Griswold, p. 154. 38Quoted in vevier, p. 141. 39Foreign Relations, 1910, pp. 235—36. 189 Since 1900 Britain had become a firm ally of Japan, and once she had negotiated her entente with France in 1904 and her rapprochement with Russia in 1907 she had little to fear in the East. Both Britain and France favored a Russo— Japanese rapprochement, already begun in 1907, to complete the circle against Germany. Only Germany showed any favorable reaction to the Knox proposal, but it was too risky for her to support it in the face of the other powers. Straight was right in believing Russia to be the key to the success of the Neutralization Plan. The Russians were divided on what policy to follow in the Far East. Kokovtsov and the financial interests favored the sale of the Chinese Eastern, while Isvolsky favored a rapprochement with Japan. Knox, by putting the ChinchowaAigun plan on a political basis, placed the problem directly before Isvolsky, and his methods of negotiation were such as to arouse all Isvolsky's suspicions. But primarily Isvolsky was afraid of Japanese power at his badk door, and without some sort of American commitment to allay these fears, the success of the Knox plan was most unlikely. Not only did Knox fail to allay Russia's fears, but he made it fairly evident that he considered Russia to be as great a threat as Japan. 40Reid, pp. 68-70, 89, 107-10, passim. 190 There was never any question of his reversing the balance of power as established by Roosevelt by supporting Russia against Japan.41 If creating opportunities for American capital were the only consideration of the Knox plan, it is curious that there was little debate on the merits of Isvolsky's counter proposal for a Kalgan-Kiakhta line which would sidestep Manchuria. This had been foreshadowed by J. O. P. Bland's project of the previous fall, but it was of no interest to the American Group except as a line of negotiation with Russia. It was precisely this reaction that convinced Isvolsky that America was playing politics, and once he was sure the Knox plan had no strong support in Europe, he was free to reject it. In July, 1910, he con- cluded the agreement with Japan consolidating their respective spheres of influence in Manchuria and Mongolia. This was the end of American railway schemes in Manchuria.42 In the summer of 1910, after the collapse of the Neutralization Proposal, the American Group sought to withdraw from the China picture. They were tired of the political maneuvers, the delays and indecision attendant 41Williams, Russian Relations, pp. 69—73. 42Vevier, pp. 155-57, 158-59, 160; E. H. Zabriskie, American-Russian Rivalry in the Far East (Philadelphia, 1946), pp. 157-65. 191 on doing business in China, and were afraid of the political responsibility should America become engaged in conflict in China. They feared public opinion would blame such conflict on their search for profit. The Group was persuaded to continue only after strong representations from Straight. Huntington Wilson, Knox and finally Taft, and they agreed only on the condition that they conclude no contracts likely to arouse the opposition of other powers. This condition would relieve them of all political responsibility.43 Surely if the promotion of American business abroad had been the only purpose of the Taft administration, the efforts employed to persuade American financiers to take care of their own interests went beyond the call of duty. The negotiations for the Hukuang loan had been going on during this period. It is not necessary to follow them in detail except to examine America's reasons for joining them. Charles Vevier has argued that America's interest in taking part in Chinese loans was entirely economic. He states that the attention of the State Department was drawn to the competition by British, German and French interests for a proposed Hankow—Canton railway loan in the fall of 43Vevier, pp. 163-65; Croly, pp. 339-44. 192 1908 by Selwyn Tait of the International Banking Corporation, which had close ties with the National City Bank. As a result Huntington Wilson instructed Rockhill to investigate the situation in Peking. Rockhill was put off by the Chinese, and the International Banking Corporation's efforts between January and April, 1909, to join the loan did not succeed. In May, 1909, bankers of the three powers signed an agreement for sharing the proposed loan, which was also to include a Hankow-Szechuan line. With the proposed centralization of the Chinese railway system, which Straight had already reported to Washington, such a monopoly of an important loan meant a decided blow to any hopes for American capital investment in China. These developments, vevier maintains, led Huntington Wilson to get assurances from J. P. Morgan and Company and the International Banking Corporation that they were ready to undertake Chinese loans, and with this economic backing he sent a telegram on May 24 to Rockhill telling him to request a share in the so-called Hukuang loan on the basis of somewhat shaky claims for the financing of the Hankow- Szechuan railway dating back to 1903.45 Straight then 44vevier, pp. 98—99. 45Foreign Relations, 1909. PP. 144-48. 155-56, 175-77. 193 approached Harriman and Jacob Schiff of Kuhn, Loeb and Company. The Harriman interests, Kuhn, Loeb, J. P. Morgan, the National City Bank and the First National Bank were to constitute the American Group of bankers, formed on June 11, 1909. The International Banking Corporation was not included. vevier maintains that it was significant that all but the First National Bank had been active on the China scene.46 This was not the case, however. The International Banking Company, for which vevier claims the State Department had first acted, was not included in the Group at all, and its affiliate, the National City Bank, had no Chinese connections. Moreover Morgan had not been active on the China scene since the demise of the American China Development Company. Harriman was involved in China only through Straight's scheme for the Chinchow-Aigun line, the agreement for which had not yet been concluded. The only approach to the State Department for help in joining the Hukuang loan had come from the International Banking Corporation, which finally took no part in the transaction. The other banks agreed to join the American Group only after they were asked to do so by the State Department. 46vevier, pp. 105-06. 194 American bankers on the whole had shown little real interest in China. In 1905, when the British had asked whether America wished to take up her option on the Hankow- Chungking line (in Szechuan), F. B. Loomis, Acting Secretary of State, reported that there was no interest among American capitalists, although the State Department had publicized the opportunity.47 As late as 1908 the British bankers sought allies in the National City Bank and the First National Bank in their feud with the German bankers, and met with refusal.48 Apart from the Straight-Harriman plans, there were no other American railway loans under discussion in China in 1909.49 As we have seen most American investment was in Canada and Central America. In explaining why she had not consulted America about the Hukuang loan, China stated among other reasons that "everyone believed the Americans had plenty of use for their money at home.”50 Not only does Vevier overemphasize the interest of American bankers in China, but he mistakes the cause for sending the May 24 telegram. America had been aware before 47Foreign Relations, 1909, pp. 147-48 48Vevier, p. 96. 49 . Croly, p. 281; Griswold, p. 142. 50Foreign Relations, 1909, p. 174. 195 Selwyn Tait's information that negotiations were in progress for a British loan. The British Ambassador, Durand, had informed the United States in October, 1905, of Britain's intention to go ahead with its option on the Hankow-Szechuan route, and he had asked if America wished to act on her option. Sir Edward Grey noted in 1909 that the negotiations which had been in progress since 1905 were common knowledge.51 If the State Department knew of the loan negotiations long before 1909. why did it delay so long in taking action?52 The fact is that the State Department had been moving for some time in the direction of a more active policy in China. A policy of American participation in Chinese loans had been advocated for some time by Straight, Huntington 'Wilson and William Phillips, who had tried to put their ideas into practice when Tang was in Washington in November, 1908. The change of administration brought their views to the fore. and the agreement between British, German and French 51Foreign Relations, 1909, pp. 147, 149-50. 52Reid maintained that America acted at the time she did because it was not until late May that she learned the Hankow-Szechuan route was to be included in the tripartite loan, and it was for this line America had the option (p. 29). This is based on the evidence in Foreign Relations, 1909, p. 205. This seems to contradict Grey's assumption that it was common knowledge that this line had been under discussion since 1905. 196 bankers over the Hukuang loan finally precipitated action by the State Department. But perhaps equally important in determining American policy was the change of regime in China at about the same time as the American change of administrations. The death of the Empress Dowager and Emperor, and the fall of the Yuan Shih Kai Government in December and January, 1908-09, brought many pro-Japanese elements into the Peking government. The new regime was weak, and there was a renewal of foreign concession hunting which threatened the territorial integrity of China.53 The Taft administration entered the Hukuang loan not just because a bankers' agreement threatened to cut off American capital, but as part of a considered policy that had been advocated by members of the previous administration. This policy hoped to replace the practice of each nation controlling a section of China through exclusive concessions by establishing a united front of the powers to lend money to China. While the agreement between the British, French and German bankers might seem a step in this direction, it was an uneasy truce in the German-British rivalry, and 53Reid. pp. 13-14, 23. 197 there were fears of a reversion to the old "spheres of influence."54 As part of a consortium America would be in a better position to mediate disputes between the powers and influence the terms of loans to ensure the financial integrity of China. Fletcher the American Charge d'Affaires, indicated one kind of pnoblem the policy was designed to prevent when he reported the terms of the tripartite agreement with China of June 6, 1909. Fletcher had heard that associates of J. O. P. Bland would try to interest American capital in other China enterprises. ”It is very likely that money will be offered to China freely on terms as good or better than those [of Bland's associates] and there is some danger she will be tempted to borrow more than sound principles of finance will justify.”55 Another problem that had arisen from the competition of the powers to gain concessions was the tendency to seek security for the loans in provincial revenues, which clearly hampered Chinese control of her finances. The first instance of this practice was the German concession for the Tientsin- Chinkiang railway, Which was reported to the State Department 54Foreign Relations, 1909, p. 205. 55Foreign Relations, 1909, p. 154. 198 in January, 1908. This contract pledged the likin and other internal revenues of three provinces. A similar provision appeared in the Hukuang agreement of June, 1909. By the Commercial Treaty of 1903 America was pledged to the removal of the likig, so that its application to a loan agreement was clearly contrary to American views. Root registered no protest to the German agreement in 1908, but in June, 1909, Knox wrote: The proposed hypothecation of Chinese internal revenues for the flotation of which the United States is entitled to participation at least must therefore be regarded as involving serious political considerations. [This makes it] of the greatest importance that the United States Should participate therein in order that this Government, owing to its lien on the provincial revenues, may be in a position to exercise an influence equal to that of the other three powers in any question arising through the pledging of these levies and to enable the United States, moreover. at the proper time again to support China in her endeavor in securing the abolition of likin and the increase of the customs tariff.56 The cooperative policy was an effort to apply the open door policy to financial investment as well as commerce. A State Department memorandum of September 30, 1909, ex- plained the policy that was already in effect. If China is to develop industrially as an independent political unit, the aid it receives from other 56Foreign Relations, 1909, p. 160. See also Foreign Relations, 1908, p. 200. 199 countries must be distributed in a manner to prevent any partisan domination at the capital. The nations that finance the great Chinese railways and other enterprises will be foremost in the affairs of China and the participation of American capital in these investments will give the voice of the United States more authority in political controversies in that country which will go far toward guaranteeing the preservation of the administrative entity of China.57 The memorandum went on to point out the threat to the Philippines if other countries dominated China. In urging the British to admit the United States to the loan, Knox stressed the cooperative policy. He instructed Ambassador Reid in London . . . to point out [to the British Foreign Minister] the menace to foreign trade likely to ensue from the lack of proper sympathy between the powers most vitally interested in the preservation of the principle of equality of commercial opportunity, and to add that the Government of the United States regards full and frank cooperation as best calcu- lated to maintain the open door and the integrity of China, and to state that the formation of a powerful American, British, French and German financial group would further that end.58 That the cooperative policy was not merely an excuse to push American capitalists into the Hukuang Loan was demonstrated later by the fact that America sought to include the other three powers in the Currency Reform Loan and to maintain the united front in the non-financial problem of 57Quoted in Griswold, p. 144. 58Foreign Relations, 1909, p. 152. 200 recognizing the new Chinese republic. Once America won the right to participate in the loan, the agreement that had been reached by the tripartite bankers with China had to be revised. Straight, as agent for the American group, went to London to work out America's share in the loan. Faced with the antagonism of the European bankers, he was ready to accept a share smaller than that of the European powers. The State Department would not accept this and insisted on an equal share even if this jeopardized the whole negotiation. Huntington Wilson tele- graphed angrily to Whitelaw Reid in London where the bankers were meeting that "the pledge of China and its interpretation are official matters concerning only the Governments of the United States and of China and that these Governments have no differences on the subject.” He concluded: If the banking syndicate which undertook to sustain the American policy of equal participation ignore the national aspects of the transaction, or fail to cooperate in the broad purpose in View, the Government will seek other instrumentalities to secure proper American recognition; that it should be clearly understood that this Government is interested purely for broad national reasons; that the Government alone has any rights in this matter; and that it holds such rights in trust for the good of general American interests in China.59 59Foreign Relations, 1909, pp. 169-71. 201 The details of America's share in the loan took nearly a year of wrangling to complete. An agreement between the bankers of the four powers was reached in May,1910, and it was another year before the final agreement with China was concluded, in May, 1911. Even after the conclusion of these negotiations, nothing came of the agreement because meanwhile new problems had arisen. There was increasing opposition to the loan within China, and a growing instability of the Chinese government which by summer, 1911, faced civil war. In addition there was strong opposition to the loan from Russia and Japan. In the summer of 1910 a new opportunity for American loans to China arose with the desire of the Chinese government to contract a loan for currency and tariff reforms. The Chinchow-Aigun railroad and the Knox Neutralization Plan had come to nothing, and the Hukuang loan was still entangled in talk. The American government was anxious to recover prestige as well as continue its policy of strengthening China through cooperative aid. In the fall of 1909 and again in the summer of 1910 NBnchurian officials were negotiating with British and German interests for a loan to establish a Manchurian bank for development and reforms in that region. Straight urged 202 the American Group to protest on the basis of its prior interest through Tang's proposals of 1908. The Chinese did not recognize the validity of the Tang agreement, and while both the American Group and the tripartite group (as it had become) were ready to accept the other, each wanted its prior claim recognized. Straight, in urging the American protest, may have been motivated by a desire to establish American economic supremacy in Manchuria; or he may have been mainly concerned to ensure that China made a reasonable financial arrangement and to prevent competition between the powers.60 There were strained relations between the State Department and the Group because each was acting without consultation with the other. According to vevier the Manchurian bank loan ”was not an end in itself and had no great interest for the American Group; but once the American-claimed financial position in Manchuria was threatened, the project became a device to avow the supremacy of American rights and gain access to international money markets for the sale of bonds."61 If this was really the case, the Chinese did not see it that way. They ended the impasse over the Manchurian 60Vevier, pp. 171-73. While Vevier notes all these reasons, he considered loyalty to American financial interests as the primary reason. 61vevier, p. 175. 203 loan by subordinating it to a general loan to China for currency and other reforms, and sought this loan from America alone. They made their request to the American Government, not to the bankers' syndicate. They asked America to send a financial advisor before the other powers heard of the proposal.62 A preliminary agreement was reached on October 27, 1910, by which China permitted other powers to share in the loan provided only the American Group signed and issued the bonds.63 The United States was interested in the loan because it offered an opportunity to introduce capital into Manchuria as well as help reforms in China proper. The right to share with the other powers was included in the agreement for a number of reasons. The State Department and Straight believed that only through joint action could Chinese financial reforms be made to work because they were so dependent on the cooperation of the other powers. A memorandum from Knox to the Chinese stated that ”the aim of American policy [in all the negotiations] has been to secure a sympathetic and practical cooperation of the Great Powers in maintaining the political integrity of China by making it to the interest of each to support 62Foreign Relations, 1912, pp. 89,90. 63Foreign Relations, 1912, p. 91. 204 such a policy."64 The bankers themselves also favored a cooperative policy because one of the conditions on which they had continued on the China scene in the summer of 1910 was that they would undertake no loans to which other powers objected. Moreover there was doubt that the American Group alone could raise such a large loan,65 an indication that domestic economic pressures were not involved in the desire for loans to China. Consequently, the First International Consortium for China was formed in November, 1910, by British, French, German and American banks for future loans to China. America held a somewhat independent position with regard to the Currency Loan, for which she alone held the agreement with China, but she was to seek from China the permission for the others to enter. The Consortium did not extend to the ChinchoweAigun concession, which the American Group still held, nor to the Hukuang Loan, for which there was a separate agreement. Negotiations for the entry of the other powers into the Currency Reform Loan became entangled, among other issues, in the problem of sending a financial advisor to the Chinese government. Straight and the State Department 64Foreign Relations, 1912, p. 93. See also Croly, pp. 349-51. 65Vevier, p. 178; Croly, pp. 350, 344. 205 differed in their views on the problem. Washington was concerned with American prestige and wanted to insist that the advisor be American; Straight felt that concession should be made to Chinese sensibilities.66 In addition the Chinese were objecting to the monopolistic power of the Consortium which prevented their playing off the powers against each other. The British and German interests were half-hearted about the cooperative venture, and the Russians and Japanese were objecting to the Manchurian aspects of the agreement.67 Despite these obstacles, an agreement for the entry of British, German and French interests in the currency loan was finally reached in April, 1911, a month before the final Hukuang loan agreement. Both agreements were overshadowed in China by the gathering revolutionary storms and the more immediate problems of the Yuan Shih Kai government which, needing money to exist at all, sought an advance on the Currency Reform Loan for administrative purposes.68 The situation soon became almost hopeless. On the one hand the bankers were under- standably reluctant to lend money to a regime so weak, without any economic reforms by China that would guarantee some 66Vevier, pp. 182-83; Croly, pp. 372-78. 67Vevier, pp. 180-87; Croly, pp. 372-97. 68Foreign Relations, 1912, p. 101 passim. 206 stability to the financial situation. On the other hand, the more America pressed reform on the Chinese government, the more it weakened the prestige of the central government in the eyes of the Chinese, and, despite the cooperative policy, aroused the suspicions of the other powers. Russia and Japan were unalterably opposed to any loans for development in Manchuria, and France and Britain were tied by their respective alliances to Russia and Japan. Britain again showed her hand on the question of the open door by renewing the Anglo-Japanese Alliance in July, 1911, with no effort to restrain Japan as the price of agreement. The alliance this time was aimed at Germany, not Russia. Only Germany was interested in the integrity of China but was restricted by her isolated diplomatic position. America was, as always, limited in her power to act in China, and by intruding herself on the scene tended to press the Chinese government into a position that could not be defended.6 The request of the Chinese for an advance on the Currency Reform Loan created a further dilemma because the lending powers were not agreed on whether to support Yuan's government.7O Knox favored a position of neutrality between 69Reid. PP. 150. 184-85, 196. 198, 205-08. 222-24 passim; Griswold, pp. 165-69. 70Foreign Relations, 1912, pp. 103-05. 207 the two Chinese factions hoping they would reach a mogug vivendi before any loans were made. The refusal of the Consortium to lend money weakened Yuan's control in the North and thus his bargaining power with the regime in the South. He was compelled to negotiate loans with other international groups on terms that were financially hazardous, thus risking further foreign intervention in China. The prevention of such loans had been one of the objects of the Consortium, yet its own refusal to lend money did not help China. It is clear that any loan to China at this stage would have been hazardous and purely political in intent. Since the western governments were working through commercial channels, a loan for political purposes alone could not be considered. The pressures by Russia and Japan to enter the consortium, in order to hinder the Manchurian aspects of the Currency Reform loan or to break up the consortium altogether. completed the devastation of the Taft-Knox policy in China.71 By the end of 1912 the American bankers were again considering abandoning the China field by leaving the Consortium. They had only signed the agreement in June to include Russia and Japan on Taft's urging. With the coming to power of the Wilson administration, which refused to 71Foreign Relations, 1912, pp. 99-100, 114, passim; Vevier, pp. 200-01. 208 support their activity, they withdrew completely from Chinese affairs.72 The China policy of the Taft regime, which received much of its inspiration from Willard Straight, tried to achieve a combination of political and economic ends by economic means exclusively. The contrast of this policy with that of Roosevelt is clearly revealed in Knox's reply to the letter Roosevelt addressed to Taft in 1910 on the question of Manchuria.73 Knox first said that he failed to see the essential connection which Roosevelt had made between Manchuria and the problem of Japanese immigration. He went on to say: Why the Japanese should think that we ought to accept the observance by them of one treaty right due from them to us as an offset for the disregard by them of another treaty right [in Manchuria] due from them to us I cannot understand . . . We have no desire or intention to interfere with any legitimate purpose of Japan in Manchuria. We do not care how many of her people she may send to Manchuria nor to what extent she may avail herself of her commercial opportunities there, provided in so doing she scrupulously respects the equal rights of others. Nor have we given Japan at any time just cause to think that we wished to interfere. The opinion expressed by Lord Kitchener that Japan needs Manchuria for any legitimate purpose any more than she now has by right, is also open to question. Commercially she is most advantageously situated, and 72Vevier, pp. 201—05. 73See above, Chapter V. 209 strategically she is in a position to throw troops quickly into Manchuria over her two or three lines of railways. Why the Japanese need Manchuria any more than does China, who own it now, or why it is any more ”vital" to them than to China is not apparent. I admit that reference to the ”Open Door" has frequently been abused, often through misunderstanding of what was meant by the expression. What we mean by the ”Open Door" in Manchuria is surely nothing more than fair play for our commercial interests, which certainly are not insignificant, and for China. territorially and administratively. That certainly is the meaning of our policy in China as enunciated by Secretary Hay and continued and developed under your Administration. The aim of the present Administration has been merely to reduce the theory to practice . . . Whether the American people would ever go to war or not in defense of our interests in China I am not prepared to say. It might depend upon the nature of the provocation. But in any case it certainly is not for us to prejudice our case at the start by admitting to the world that we would not, under any circumstances, go to war. We can at least allow others to draw their own conclusions.74 Whereas Roosevelt regarded it beyond America's ability to influence affairs in Manchuria and not worth the risk of antagonizing Japan, Taft and Knox regarded the preservation of China's integrity, including Manchuria, as of primary importance. They apparently did not agree with Roosevelt's estimation that America would never fight over China. Yet Taft and Knox were faced with the same refusal by Congress to make any binding commitments to other countries 74Quoted in Reid, p. 183. 210 of a military or diplomatic nature, and the same lack of public interest in China which Roosevelt faced. They hoped, therefore, to use financial in place of military and political power to achieve their ends. This proved to be a crude weapon, hard to manipulate and essentially ineffective against the opposition it faced in the Far East. While there were many mistakes made in negotiating the Knox Neutralization Proposal and the various loan agreements, it seems hard to conceive that any of them could have succeeded even with perfect diplomacy in the face of the European antagonisms involved, the expansionist tendencies of Japan, and the weakness and vacillations of the Chinese government. If America had been prepared to apply military force or to conclude a diplomatic alliance; if even one of the European powers had been prepared to play America's game; or if the Chinese government had taken a strong stand, conceivably one or all of these plans might have succeeded. A certain amount of ill luck also attended America's efforts to uphold the integrity of China through strengthening her economy. The changes in the Chinese government in the winter of 1908-09 undermined Tang's negotiations with Harriman at a time when an agreement might have turned the scales in China. The death of Harriman and the confusion in the 211 instructions to Rockhill for presenting the Neutralization Proposal were other chance events that added to America's difficulties. The whole situation presented a dilemma ignored by the economic theory of imperialism. Here was a backward nation that had at last decided it needed to modernize, not only to improve the welfare of its people, but to gain sufficient strength to maintain its independence. In order to do so it needed capital which was not available at home. Capital abroad could only come from private sources. But private_sources would not lend without a certain security for the loan. This problem was magnified by the instability of the Chinese regime. Moreover, however good the intention, business propositions in China were bound to become entangled in politics. In the first place loans were always made to the government, not to private corporations; any dispute over terms or interpretations of contracts, therefore, became diplomatic problems. Secondly, by 1909 the interests of the European nations had become so great in China that European power struggles were always reflected on the China scene. CONCLUSION The economic interpretation of imperialism has had wide acceptance. It is a plausible and easily grasped formula that can lead to oversimplification in the hands of historians. It became the popular interpretation of events by historians who wrote in the period following the First World War through the 1930's, when with the activity of the dictators compelled historians to seek new interpretations of the origins of imperialism. Nevertheless the economic view and the concept of the banker and businessman as villain has remained well entrenched in historical writing. Aside from any possible theoretical objections to the economic theory as expounded in Leninist and Marxist dogma or in the more liberal analysis of Hobson, there can be found many shortcomings to the theory when one applies it to a given historical period. It is to be hoped that the foregoing chapters offer an example of the weaknesses of the theory as applied to American foreign policy in China during the heyday of American imperialistic enthusiasm at the turn of the last century. Despite grandiose hopes for the China market, America had a relatively small economic stake in China in this period. Her investments in 1900 were negligible, and 212 213 they were still comparatively low fourteen years later, despite many efforts in the interim to bolster her investment. American trade was substantial in a few products, notably cotton, but the total was never of sufficient weight to create a formidable pressure group in America or to account alone for the government's interest in China. Since policy is carried out by individual men, what— ever the weight of general economic trends, it is important to discover the aims and problems of the individual states— men. The proponents of the so—called ”large theory" at the end of the century were influenced by an intellectual climate that stressed considerations quite different from the economic ones. The themes that found most expression in contemporary writing about world affairs in general and China in particular were: (1) variations of Social Darwinism that emphasized competition, struggle and power in international affairs; (2) a desire to save ”civilization” from the threats of barbarism or alien civilizations; (3) as a corollary to this desire a belief in an American or an Anglo-Saxon mission to spread the benefits of democracy; (4) a nationalism that stressed prestige and honor as well as noblesse oblige for the richer nations, such as America had become. For a variety of reasons China played a crucial part in all these theories. 214 At the turn of the century America entered the world stage for the first time to take part in events and decisions of world wide importance. Because of the belief in the importance of China in the struggle of civilizations and in the balance of power in Asia, America regarded her national interest as bound up with the territorial and administrative integrity of the moribund empire which was threatened by encroachments from the European powers. It was believed that this purpose could be achieved at the same time that we fostered our own trade and financial interests. The policy was formulated by Hay and Rockhill and expanded by Taft and Knox. There was a certain drawing back by Roosevelt. He did not abrogate the open door policy toward China, but his greater concern with Japan meant a neglect of China during his administration. America's policy was marked by blunders and naiveté and like most national policies it was not always consistent. The effectiveness of the policy was hindered by two things: a frequent ignoring or ignorance of the European alliances and rivalries that influenced events in the Far East; and the refusal of the nation or the Congress to support any decisive action in this part of the world. Since America refused to resort to arms or to become involved in entangling diplomatic alliances, American power to influence decisions 215 was limited to economic pressure and moral suasion, which could be of some significance on occasion but was never decisive. Given the situation she faced in Asia and the limitations on her ability to act. it is perhaps remarkable that America accomplished anything. China was weak and indecisive, and at certain periods close to anarchy. Russia and Japan who both had expansionist dreams were in a strong strategic position to press their demands on China. England, who could no more have sent an army to China than America, was isolated in Europe at the turn of the century. Needing support to protect India, she formed an alliance with Japan. This tended to deprive America of England's support in China, and may even have encouraged Japanese aggression. The French alliance played a similar role for Russia; and Germany squeezed between Russia and England in Europe, had to play a cautious role in the Far East. The British-Russian entente in 1907 and the Russo-Japanese agreement in 1910 completed the isolation of America in the Pacific. In the absence of support from Congress or public opinion, the government had to uphold what it regarded as America's long term political interests in Asia by using the limited economic interests available. These were 216 never great enough in themselves to warrant committing American arms in their defense, and because of their weakness American policy succeeded in China only when the international climate was temporarily favorable. BIBLIOGRAPHY United States Government Documents and Publications Some important State Department documents are published in Papers Relating to the Foreign Relations of the United States (Washington) of which the years from 1898 to 1912 were consulted for this study. Since the documents for each year were selected for publication the following year, there are obvious limitations to the material which could be made available. In the case of United States relations with many countries the documents were limited to trivia, but an exceptional candor appeared in the selection for China,an indication perhaps that the State Department felt it had no ulterior motives in its China policy. Supplementary material on official relations with China appear in Consular Reports, Shanghai, General Records of the State Department, Record Group 59, Vbls. 45-53 (on microfilm), which cover“ the years 1899 to 1906 when the Consular Service was reorganized. Shanghai was selected for special study because it had the largest international settlement in Northern China, and was a major port for American trade. In addition to the many documents of a routine nature, there are scattered letters and reports on 217 218 events of a wider significance which, when not directly applicable to this study, provided useful background information. The Shaping of American Diplomacy, ed. by William Appleman Williams (Chicago, 1956% a book of readings and interpretive comments by the editor, gives the text of some important policy documents in an accessible form, as well as reprinting pertinent journal articles from scattered sources. The Statistical Abstract of the United States (Washington) published each year for the previous year, provided some statistical information on trade with China. More detailed information appears in the Monthly Summary of Commerce and Finance of the United States (Washington). The December issues for the years 1899 to 1912 were consulted. In addition to these, scattered statistical information on market conditions in China appear in three Special Consular Reports: Foreign Markets for American Cotton Manufacturers, Special Consular Report, Vol. XXXVI (Washington, 1905); George E. Anderson, Cotton-Goods Trade in China, Special Consular Report No. 44 (Washington, 1911); George E. Anderson, Railway Situation in China, Special Consular Report No. 48 (Washington, 1911). 219 Private Papers, Letters, Biographies The Letters of Theodore Roosevelt, 8 Vols., ed. by Elting E. Morison, John M. Blum, John J. Buckley (Cambridge, Mass., 1951) was the most useful, as well as the most enjoyable documentary source used in this study. Roosevelt wrote with candor and at length his views on just about everything. A student usually has good evidence of what he thought on any problem at a given time, although he must be wary of Roosevelt's egocentricity and lapses of memory after the event. Special mention must be made of Elting E. Morison's introduction to Volume Five which is a stimulating essay on Roosevelt's personality and intellectual outlook. Roosevelt's public writings are collected in The Works of Theodore Roosevelt, Memorial Edition, 24 Vols.(New York, 1924). The Letters and Friendships of Sir Cecil Sprinngice, 2 Vols., ed. by Stephen L. Gwynn (Boston and New York, 1929) is useful for the ideas which Spring Rice was expressing to Roosevelt as well as his comments on the American scene. The letters from Roosevelt printed here are also published in their entirety in Roosevelt Letters. Similarly the Roosevelt letters in Selections from the Correspondence of Theodore Roosevelt and Henry Cabot Lodge, 1884-1918, 2 Vols. (New York, 1925) are reprinted in Morison's edition. The Lodge letters here printed add little to the understanding of Far 220 Eastern affairs. William Roscoe Thayer's The Life and Letters of John Hay (Boston and New York, 1915) is sketchy and now superceded. A number of biographies have been useful in providing material from other private papers not available for use in this study. Tyler Dennett's John Hay: From Poetry to Politics (New York, 1933) is well organized and very readable but lacks detailed information on many aspects of Hay's policy. Moreover it was written before other documents, such as the Rookhill papers, were available. Paul A. Varg's ngg Door Diplomat: The Life of W. W. Rockhill (Urbana, 1952) not only fills many of the gaps on the formation of the open door policy and later developments, but presents some perceptive insights on the mainsprings of American policy. It is a succinct and balanced account of the life of a key diplomat. A mature analysis of Roosevelt's outlook on the world as well as of his strengths and weakness as a statesman is provided in Howard K. Beale, Theodore Roosevelt and the Rise of America to World Power (Baltimore, 1956). Philip C. Jessup made a thorough study of the Root papers for his detailed biography, Elihu Root, 2 Vols. (New York, 1938) which gives a balanced judgment on some controversial issues. Two works are based on the crucial Willard Straight papers, which are in private hands. Herbert Croly, a friend and 221 admirer of Straight, presents the events surrounding the Chinese loan negotiations in a biographical context in Willard Straight (New York, 1924). This is an attractive book with lengthy quotations from Straight's private diary and personal letters, illustrated profusely with Straight's own sketches. Its usefulness is marred by a total absence of documentation or index. Charles vevier, The United States and China, 1906-1913: A Study of Finance and Diplomacy (New Brunswidk, 1955) draws not only on the Straight papers but a wide variety of private papers and government documents to give a diplomatic history of the events in China. His facts do not disagree with those given by Croly, but he gives a different interpretation to the role of the financiers in the formation of American policy. Henry Fowles Pringle's two biographies, The Life and Times of William Howard Taft, 2 Vols. (New York, Toronto, 1939) and Theodore Roosevelt: A Biography (New York, 1956) were useful for background information but do not deal with foreign policy in detail. Similarly John A. Garraty, Henry Cabot Lodge: A Biography (New York, 1953) and George Kennan, E. H. Harriman: A Biography,2 Vols. (Boston and New York, 1922), added nothing on the situation in the Far East. The memoirs of Lloyd C. Griscom, Diplomatically Speaking (Boston, 1940), and F. M. Huntington Wilson, Memoirs of an Ex-diplomat (Boston, 1945), 222 both proved disappointing. On the Economic Interpretation of Imperialism The economic interpretation of imperialism has rested largely on the theories presented in J. A. Hobson, Imperialism: A Study (London, 1948) and Nikolai Lenin (V. I. Lenin), Imperialism (New York, 1939). An important work by an economist, E. M. Winslow, The Pattern of Imperialism (New York, 1948), combines a history of the development of the economic interpretation of imperialism with an incisive analysis of the assumptions of the theory. Charles A. Beard makes some important contributions of his own to the economic theory as well as a provocative presentation of some aspects of American history in The Idea of National Interest (New York, 1934). His ideas are expressed again in a brief work, A Foreign Policy for America (New York, London, 1940). The Contemporary View of the Period A number of books written at the turn of the century might be classed with the papers of statesmen as giving a contemporary view of world affairs. The expansionist view is given clear expression in three books by Captain Alfred T. Mahan, The Influence of Sea Power Upon History, 1660-1783 (Boston, 1890); The Interest of America in Sea Power Present 223 and Future (Boston, 1897), and The Problem of Asia and its Effect Upon International Policies (Boston, 1900), and in Brooks Adams, America's Economic Supremacy (New York, 1947). The anti-imperialist view as expressed in Paul S. Reinsch, World Politics at the End of the Nineteenth Century as Influenced by the Oriental Situation (New York, London, 1925), which was first published in 1900, bears many resemblances to the views of the expansionists. Henry Adams, The Education of Henry Adams (New York, 1931), is both a commentary on and a reflection of the ideas and historical forces at the end of the nineteenth century. The Economic Background C. F. Remer, Foreign Investments in China (New York, 1933) is an exhaustive study of the very complex problem of Chinese finances based on the work of an international team of experts, and was invaluable in this study. Remer's earlier work, The Foreign Trade of China (Shanghai, 1926) proved less useful because it does not give a detailed picture of each nation's trade with China. Charles S. Campbell, Jr., Special Business Interests and the Open Door Policy (New Haven, 1951) has much useful information on the interests that supported the open door and their activities yet does not overemphasize their importance. 224 General Histories For the period it covers, John Gilbert Reid, The Manchu Abdication and the Powers, 1908-1912 (Berkeley, 1935) is invaluable. It gives an almost day to day account of the international diplomatic negotiations concerning China, and a sound analysis of the policies of the Great Powers. Its strictly chronological organization, however, makes it difficult to use in following any given problem, and more recent information changes the picture in detail. For the period of the Boxer Rebellion, Chester A. Tan's The Boxer Catastrophe (New York, 1955) is a useful account which draws on Chinese sources. A colorful account of Chinese court intrigues at this time appears in J. O. P. Bland and E. Backhouse, China Under the Empress Dowager: Being the History of the Life and Times of Tzu Hsi (Boston and New YOrk, 1914). Edward H. Zabriskie, American—Russian Rivalry in the Far East: A Study in Diplomacy and Power, 1895-1914 (Philadelphia, 1946) is a sound and detailed study. William Appleman Williams, American-Russian Relations. 1781-1947 (New York, 1952), which covers the period of this study in less detail, is provocative but far less reliable than Zabriskie. A history of American policy toward China since the Open Door Notes, A. Whitney Griswold, The Far Eastern Policygof the United States (New York, 1938) has been a standard work 225 for almost a quarter of a century. Griswold combines a wealth of information with a distinctive point of view. Another standard work, William L. Langer, Diplomagy of Imperialism (New Ybrk, 1951) is important for the European background of the Far Eastern situation, although the book ends with the year 1902. Two textbooks, G. Nye Steiger, A History of the Far East (Boston, etc., 1944) and Harold M. Vinacke, A History of the Far East in Modern Times (New York, 1950) were occasionally useful for references. Other Works Used Richard Hofstadter, Social Darwinism in American Thought, 1860-1915 (Philadelphia, 1944). Robert Osgood, Ideals and Self-Interest in American Foreign Relations (Chicago, 1953). Arthur Meier Schlesinger, Political and Social Growth of the American People, 3rd ed. (New York, 1941). George F. Kennan, American Diplomacy, 1900—1950 (Chicago, 1951). Articles William R. Braisted, ”The United States and the American China Development Company,” Far Eastern Quarterly, Vol. XI (Feb., 1952); also reprinted in The Shapingyof American Diplomacy, ed. Williams. Braisted does a useful service in drawing together scattered government documents on 226 the relations with the company. Raymond A. Esthus, "The Changing Concept of the Open Door, Mississippi Valley Historical Review, Vol. 46 (Dec., 1959) is a provocative interpretation. Harvey Pressman, "Hay, Rockhill and China's Integrity, A Reappraisal” has some suggestions on interpreting the Rockhill-Hippisley correspondence. Robert L. Irick, ”The Chinchow-Aigun Railroad and the Knox Neutralization Plan in Ch'ing Diplomacy,‘ gives an account of the Chinese side of these negotiations based on Chinese sources. Both articles were graduate seminar papers at Harvard University and published in Papers on China, from the East Asia Regional Studies Program, Vol. 13 (Dec., 1959).