MGM PRODUCTWITIES OF INPUTS ON CASH CROP FARMS IN THE- THUMB AND WNAW VALLEY AREA OF MICHIGAN, I957 Thesis for the Dogma oI M. S. MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY M. David Brooke I958 ...... IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII IVIESI_] RETURNING MATERIALS: PIace in book drop to LJBRAfiJES remove this checkout from 4—! your record. FINES win be charged if book is returned after the date stamped be10w. HARGINAL PRODUCTIVITIES OF INPUTS 0N CASH CROP FARMS IN THE THUMB AND SAGINAW VALLEY AREA OF MICHIGAN, 1957 by M. David Brooke AN ABSTRACT Submitted to the College of Agriculture of Michigan State University of Agriculture and Applied Science in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF SCIENCE Department of Agricultural Economics 1958 Approved by 4% V%‘~ M. David Brooke ABSTRACT 1 The purpose of this study was to estimate marginal value productivities for the various input, investment and expense cate- gories of farm businesses. It was believed that such measures would provide a more objective basis for estimating efficiency of and making decisions on some of these inputs, particularly labor and machinery investment, than farm management research methods used in the past. It was anticipated the estimates, as a whole, would be valuable to farm managers, agricultural extension personnel, and representatives of lending institutions working in the area i where the study was conducted. The marginal value productivities were estimated by fitting a Cobb-Douglas function to the data collected from thirty, pur- posively sampled, cash crop farms in the Thumb and Saginaw Valley area of Michigan for the year 1957. b; bn 3 is linear in the logarithms. The data were fitted by the method This function is of the form Y = qxzbzx ....xn and of least squares to the logarithmic form of the function in order 's). The b 's are i i estimates of the elasticities of the input categories with respect to determine the regression coefficients (b to gross income. The marginal value productivities, for the geometric mean organization of the farms surveyed, were then esti- A. biY A mated from the equation MVP -= , where Y is the X1 anti10g of the geometric mean estimated gross income and X1 is the geometric mean of the input category Xi in the prediction equation. Five regression analyses of the data were made which in- cluded two assuming perfect complementarity among the input categories. 'M. David Brooke 2 The input categories, their geometric mean quantities, regression coefficients and estimated marginal value productivities for the sample were: Geometric . Marginal Mean Regression Value Input Category Quantity Coefficient Product (dollars) X2 Land 193 T.A. .224325 24.71 X3 Labor 19 months .275044 306.87 X4 Machinery investment $14,654 .204850 .29? X5 Drainage investment $19,135 .279131 .310 X6 Current fertilizer and crop expenses 3 6,609 .170704 .584 Note: These regression coefficients have been estimated from two different functions and thus the sum of these bi's is not the true sum. Geometric mean gross income was 821,252. The estimated MVP's for land and drainage investment were computed from the b 's obtained in the first Cobb-Douglas function 1 analysis. The other MVP's were estimated from bi's obtained in the final Cobb-Douglas function. This latter function assumed perfect complementarity of the inputs of land and drainage investment, which were set up as a combined limiting factor category. The MVP of this limiting factor was computed to be equivalent to 854.45 per drained tillable acre. (The average drainage investment per tillable acre was 899.90.) M. David Brooke 3 Evidence of complementarity between the inputs was found, which might have been expected in view of the high intercorrelations of the input categories. Tentative conclusions were that most of these farms were fairly well adjusted in 1957. Increasing returns to scale, indi- cated by the sum of the b '8 being persistently greater than one, 1 suggested that prOportionate increases in all inputs would be profitable, with some reservations. Land was a limiting factor on the smaller farms and raw land in general was yielding lower than expected returns, particularly in view of the high prices being paid for land in this area. Labor had a higher return than most other similar studies, particularly on livestock farms, have shown. The labor organization on these farms appeared to be ef- ficient, but with Opportunities for improvement by reducing labor requirements at sugar beet singling and hoeing time in particular. Large machinery investments have probably helped in the attainment- of such high labor returns, nevertheless returns to investment in machinery were also good, being almost equated to marginal factor cost. Returns to drainage investment were high, emphasizing the importance of drainage on these farms. 1957 was a favorable year as regards this investment; even so, a further study of drainage may be worthwhile. Less confidence could be placed in the esti- mates of the returns to the other inputs of fertilizer and crop expense. They were showing a very low return which may in part be due to a less than normal response to fertilizer because of the M. David Brooke 4 weather in 1957. More attention to these items of expenditure could result in higher returns. The use of these marginal value productivity estimates as a general advisory tool on individual farms was discussed and an example given. The conclusions were that although applications of this particular study were limited because the farms studied are so well adjusted, this method of analysis would be useful and highly|desirable in areas of more poorly adjusted farms. MARGINAL PRODUCTIVITIES 0F INPUTS ON CASH CROP FARMS IN THE THUMB AND SAGINAW VALLEY AREA OF MICHIGAN, 1957 by M. David Brooke A THESIS Submitted to the College of Agriculture of Michigan State University of Agriculture and Applied Science in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF SCIENCE Department of Agricultural Economics 1958 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The author wishes to place on record his gratitude to the many people who have assisted with this study and made it possible. Sincere thanks are due to Dr. Glenn L. Johnson for his guidance, inspiration and continuous encouragement throughout this study and, indeed, during the whole of the author's graduate work. The author is particularly indebted to the Kellogg Founda- tion for providing the fellowship which enabled graduate work to be undertaken at Michigan State University and the privilege of visiting this wonderful country of America. Thanks are also due to the Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries and Fbod of England and Isles for granting the necessary sabbatical leave and to Dr. L. L. Boger for providing the financial resources which made the study possible. Assistance and constructive criticism were freely given by many of the staff and fellow students of the Department of Agricultural Economics, particularly Professors H. L. Brown, C. R. Hoglund, J. M. Neilson and I. H. Vincent. Assistance given by members of the Departments of Agricultural Engineering, Soil Science and Fhrm Crops was also appreciated. Thanks are given to Mrs. Sally Daly and other members of the computing staff for carrying out a major portion of the computa- tions, to Miss Beverly Hamilton for translating the author's il- legible English into legible, typed American, to Mrs. Doris DeKoning for typing the final manuscript, and to G. I. Trent for his help in meeting the final deadline. ii The splendid cooperation and friendliness of the many farmers visited, and for whom the data was collected, is gratefully acknowledged and, also, the assistance given by members of the staff of the Michigan Co-operative Extension Service. Finally, the author wishes to thank his wife, Joan, for her tolerance and encouragement during the preparation and comple- tion of this study. Any errors in this manuscript are, of course, the responsi- bility of the author. iii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page 3‘ CKI‘IYC'I'YIJEDGMIENTS . O O I O O O O O O C C O I O I O O C O O O O i w. .“ fl? ,, ‘ ' t'.‘ 5' . J I..I~)T ( 1‘ F‘I 1"12.g.3 e e e s e s e e s e s s s s s e s e e s e- e s 5 J 1013? (I? Lfi-HIIJLR; e s e e e e e e e o e e s e s e e e e e s e e Vii I O INTRODIJCTION O O O O O O O O O C O O O O O O P O O A. II. PRODUCTION FUNCTION ANALYSIS . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 The Optimum A1 Iccntion of Resources . . . . . . . 7* Grouping t‘ee Inmxts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Fitting the 3sta to the CobL~UonrJaz Function , , LT Ilzrr.ossi\/e ‘Saun1fiIi;lg . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1“ III. SAMPLING PROCEDURE AND NEASURENENT TECHNIQUES . . . . TE The Smrir-I e . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ‘73 'I‘IA e DU f, 6' O O O C 0 O O I D O D O O O O f O O O --‘I 5: Correlation of Innnt Categories . . . . . . . . . 33 IV. FITTING THE PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS AND APPRAISAL OF THE STATISTICAL RESULTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . ST The First Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 'Ihe ASeCruvI F3uzctitn1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . I? TIhe 'Fhilvl Fhuxctixun, :lssxnringg ch‘fvcfi. Conq110742nt3n‘i13' of the Inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47 The Fourth Function, Assuming Perfect Conqflxunenixu‘ity (3f tin: Inrt:,s . . . . . . . . . 19 The Final Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 Complementarity cf the Inputs . . . . . , . . . . CT Managerial Ability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 iv TABLE OF CONTENTS continued» \I . EVAIJIY‘ATION s e e e e s e e e e e e e e e n e e s a Land and Investment in Drainayw . . . . . . . . I-aIJOI‘ e e e e e e e s e e e s s e s e e s e e b‘flChiIIC‘r‘Y o s s e s e s e e e e e e I e e I e o Fertil iazcx‘ Expenditure , . . . . . . . . . . . rtImr Current Crop :XIKBDSBS; . . . . . . . . . . Iauj-li'zir};ts O O O O O C O O O Q C O I 9 O O O I Increasing Returns to Scale . . . . . . . . . . The Complementarity of the Input Catogroriex; . . Reorsv‘zmizution of n Farr: on tic Basis of the \) list/mates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . IV. CONCLUSIONS AND APPLICATIONS IN THE UNITED KINGDOM Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Applications in the Unite-J King-(10m . . . . . . APPENDIX A, Estimated Marginal Value Productivity for Some or £2.63 Fill-I313 iII tile SENT?) C s e e s e e e s .U'PENDIX 1‘) Questionnaire Used in Personal Interviews . . I BIBLIOGRAPHY .... (D 9'" (:6 C. I 91 10?) LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE Page la. Relationshi; between marginal value product, total value product and price of the variable invut . . . . 6 1h. Product contour map showing: output dependent; on two inputs with other innuts held constant a . . . . . . . 6 an. The COIJb-DOU’Z‘IUS production function iIIustrnting decreasing returns to scale only . . . . . . . . . . . 1'1 2b. The Cobb-Douglas :‘wrorhxcticn surface illustrating; symmetrical asymptotic 3:04uct Contours, with straight line expansion paths . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 3. Relationship Between gross income n~d unifs of limiting factor on the far s in the sarule . . . . . 55 v 1 LIST OF TABLE TABLE PAGE I. Summnry of ewriricul data collected ffufl the t"..irt"—()!.c farms in the .sumnle . . . . . . . . . . 70 II. The margins} value productivities of the geometric mean quuntities of in uts reed on tnixt; ensh crozov ftrM-s in the Swfinnw Valley nxfl‘. 1"“me we." (‘1‘ :ICIJUSHZ, 1957 (Jerived fuvnv the first ncuuucti n function) 4p 0 I I I I O I I O 3 I I I I I I I I I I 7" III. Comparison of the estimntod bi's and the hi's necessary to yield. ruinimum zzturglnol value prov; c‘s. fir‘fit fiIUCtlon s e e s e s s e e e e e e e e e e I'L— IV. The ”standard units” cf the limiting factors used in the functiuns assuuin; perfect car Tcmenturitv of the innuf catcgoxies, with their ninimnm expected -. ,4 . ILLIII lu‘: s w e e s s e s e s s s s e e e e e e e ~ A. V. The verginul value productivitios of the geometric Inean .unurtities of'iwnnits Usuc’;n1 thirt}'(gu§: crap furvas; iii the Sarfii;z0.v \Qilleay'zxnni fiusz) . rcti (y? H l IIICIIIQE‘III, 1‘9"? ()01'iX'0d frur‘ the firm] 1‘I“K);I!1Cti\ul lhlncstjA3n, ““2ic12 11“e;itcv? I;1n(‘ :udri dl‘aixx' at Ainxwesfnneztt (If; I'IOI‘I‘QCI C'i‘rI‘IUI‘I’IItb) a e s s e e e e e s s e e ‘34 VI. Comparison of the estirruter} hi'c and the bi’s necessary to yield minimum morgi'ol VMTHe pruduCts, fiI-oni f‘II‘ICI-iI'II e I s e e s s s e e s s e e s e e If: VII. Regression coefficients and marginal value yroductivitics of one month of Inhur, in various far? ilu: nzwzu:;, c4)tuiJie(} ix: rwccei‘t ESIUZIIGri . . . . '14 VIII. Nunher of men and Inchinery investment her 190 tiIIéwbIO aficresz, I‘VICcifVIC, .U"eu Ii, Iicfiiiflurx . . . ()9 IX. Range in quantities of artificial fertilizers amplicu to the three main crops of thirty Saginaw Valley and Thumb cash crog‘ farms in 10.737 . . . . . . . . 7;; X. Estimrted rarginal Value productivities (dollars) for sure of the frnvns in the sample . . . . . . . SO CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION The British farmer is beginning to be faced with the labor problem which has plagued the American farmer for some time. Other industries are becoming more and more attractive to agricultural labor with the farmer being unable to pay comparable wage rates. The substitution of machinery for labor which has taken place in the United States, together with the increased farm size is apparently part of the answer. I111 it pay to do likewise in the United Kingdom? If so, how much does it pay? It is hoped that this study will illustrate a method of answering these ques- tions. Methods of farm management analysis commonly used in the U. K. measure labor efficiency in terms of productive work units per man. This is a measure of output per unit of input. In some instances, where large amounts of capital are used, a man may be accomplishing 500 days work per annum: It would therefore be an advantage to measure efficiency on a more objective basis. Con- tinuous function analysis provides a method of isolating the return to each input category; thus if the profit motive is taken as the criterion, efficiency could be measured in terms of the income return per unit of labor. Machinery use is obviously difficult to assess, with much subjective judgment involved. The possibility of measuring efficiency in terms of returns to investment appears attractive as it would provide some objective basis for assessing whether a farm was over or under capitalized with machinery. It was decided that cash crop farming in the Saginaw Valley and Thumb area of Michigan should provide a useful and interesting study of a method for determining the marginal value productivities of inputs by subjecting the input-output data to a continuous function regression analysis. The theoretical basis for this pro- cedure is discussed in the next chapter. The farms chosen were as purely cash crop as could be satisfactorily found. This was done in order to simplify the problem. It would have been useful to undertake the project on mixed farms but the accounting procedure necessary and the complexity of the problem, as pointed out by Beringerl and time limitations precluded the attempt. The method of sampling and measuring the productive input categories is discussed in Chapter III. The fitting of the pro- duction functions and appraisal of the statistical results follow in Chapter IV. The evaluation of these results in Chapter V in- vestigates the usefulness of the information in the area studied. Conclusions are drawn in Chapter V1 with a discussion on the appli- cation of similar methods of studying farm businesses in the U. K. lChristoph Beringer, "Problems in Finding a Method to Estimate Marginal Value Productivities for Input and Investment Categories on Multiple Enterprise Farms." (Resource Productivitya Returns to Scale and Farm Size, Heady, Johnson and Hardin, Iowa s€3%e Cbllege Press, 1956. pp. 106-113.) CHAPTER II PRODUCTION FUNCTION ANALYSIS The Optimum Allocation of Resources It is assumed that the maximization of profits or returns to investments as a means to more ultimate ends is the underlying motive of farming. Marginal analysis enables the determination of the most profitable allocation of resources; this involves estimating the change in the value of total product brought about by the last unit of productive resource used. (The marginal value product or MVP.) It is economically profitable to continue adding units of a productive resource until the addition to total cost, or Marginal Factor Cost (MFG) is just covered by the marginal value product. MVP X (1) mx -_- wax or 1(1) = 1 1( ) 1 MFC y x1 Where X1 is one of the inputs producing the product Y with all other units of input (X X3, ... Xh) remaining fixed. 29 As no one farm is generally capable of influencing either the price of the product or factor costs to his competitors perfect competition can be assumed. So that if Py is the price per unit of output Y and PJ: is the price per unit of input X , then 1 l for maximum profit NPP x l P . (z) 1 y p 3 x l The law of diminishing returns is assumed to apply to all inputs used singly and in various combinations on the farm. This assumption assures the existence of a high profit point. The law states that as inputs of a variable factor of production are added, in combination with fixed factors, the total product will first increase at an increasing rate, followed by a stage of in- creasing at a decreasing rate and finally the total product will decrease. This is illustrated in Figure Is by the total value product curve (TVP). The MVP curve is the slope of the TVP curve (or g% ). 1 It pays to add X1 as long as the output achieved covers the cost of the input; or until, at the point B , equation (1) holds. In this case, this is the optimum combination of X1 with fixed inputs X2, X3..... X3 . when two inputs are variable (X1 and X2) in combination with other fixed inputs the principle is better illustrated by a three dimensional diagram (Figure lb), or a production surface. The iso value contours are the loci of combinations of the two variable inputs, with fixed inputs (X3, X4, ..., X“), capable of producing a given amount of output, i.e., an equal elevation on the production surface. The inputs of X1 and X2 are shown measured along each axis. Output of Y is shown by the contours in the third dimension. The iso cost lines are the loci of all positive quantities that can be purchased with a given outlay. The iso value product contour tangent to an iso cost line represents the greatest value of Y produced for that given cost of using inputs X1 and X2 . This is the point of least cost combination for that output. The expansion path, or line of least cost combination (0A), is a line joining all these points of tangency at a given cost structure. Figure 1b is intended to illustrate the law of diminishing returns so that a vertical section of the production surface along the line 0A , or line of least cost combination, may look something like the TVP curve of Figure la. The X axis, in such a case, would then be designated by 1&1, le x3, xv”... xn . Though diagrammatic illustration is impossible with more than two variable inputs, the concept still holds for any number. Assuming that all factors are not variable in the period under consideration, the law of diminishing returns will operate in respect of all the variable inputs combined in proportions dic- tated by the line of least cost combination. So that for maximum profit: MVP MVP - MVP ‘2’ xl( ) x2< ) ' x“( ) ————L—' 8 ‘-_C—L C eeee = '__—-L MFCx1 MV x2 MFCxn If the MVPs of these variable inputs increase as all variable inputs are increased, the firm is experiencing increasing returns to scale, as a whole and with respect to each input. If the MVPs decrease as the variable inputs continue to increase the firm is experiencing decreasing returns to scale. It continues to pay adding units of production as long as the resultant increment to total value product covers the increased (In dollars) 1 Figure 1a. ’PVP XII X2, X3, ..., Xn (In dollars) Relationship between marginal value product, total value product and price of the variable input. \ \ \ \ \ ‘ W \ \ \ s \ \ \ \ x ‘\ \\ \\ iso value X T \ \ \ contours 1 \ \ \ \ x \ x J \ \ \ \ \ ' \ \ \ I? \\ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ ‘\ \ . t \ \fi _, iso cos " \ \\ \ \ lines \ \ \\ \\ \ \ ‘\ \ \ \ \ x “\ \\ ‘\ . \ \ ‘ \ \ \ \\ ‘ \\ d \ \ \ \ \ \ \ \ ¥ - \i \ \ \ _ v v v 1 7 I l l I ‘ x2 Figure lb. Product contour map showing output dependent on two inputs with other inputs held constant. cost of production, i.e., until equation (2) holds. If the marginal value product of one input exceeds that of another it pays to increase the use of that input before the other. For example, it may be found that the return to drainage investment (measured in dollars) is 20 percent, while the return to the in- vestment in land (measured in acres) is 830 per acre. The cost of undrained land is, say, 3400 per acre and assuming that a 5 percent return on land or drainage investment is necessary to cover interest on borrowed capital, maintenance, tax charges, etc., it would leave a net return on capital of 2%:percent for land and 15 percent for drainage investment. If this farmer had the choice of either buying more land, assuming normal capital restrictions, or completing the drainage of his existing land, it would pay him to do the latter until the conditions in equation (2) hold true. In practice, such decisions must necessarily be made more subjectively. The prestige value of a larger acreage may outweigh the difference in return to be expected from increasing the drainage rather than the land investment. This depends on the utility function of the individual manager. Also, such decisions must consider the future outlook of prices of land and farm products. Other risks and uncertainties involving weather and government policy may also be subjectively considered. The same is true of labor supplied by the farmer and his family which may have no established market price. Though such considerations are not currently ignored, it is sug- gested that a somewhat more objective basis would be of great assistance. Grouping the Inputs The principles outlined are applied to data from the farms surveyed in this research project. The inputs have been carefully grouped into independent categories (Chapter III) in terms of substitutability and complementarity. Classification is necessary in order to simplify reality. N variables, while theoretically solvable in a production function, make the task of determining the point of maximum profit extremely difficult. Johnson suggests:1 (l) The inputs within a category should be as near perfect substitutes or complements as possible. (2) Substitutes should be combined, as perfect substitutes are really one input which can be measured in terms of the least common denominator causing them to be good substitutes and priced in dollar value of the least common denominator. For example, the least common denominator of 5-10-10 and 6-12-12 fertiliser inputs would be units made up of equal amounts of N, P, and K, measured in terms of their dollar value. (3) Complements should be combined, as perfect complements are really one input made up of the complements combined in constant proportions. They should be measured by counting the "sets” of such good complements in their proper proportions and priced on an index basis with constant weights assigned to each complement. 1Lawrence A. Bradford and Glenn L. Johnson, Farm Management Analysis (New York: John Wiley and Sons,Inc., 1953), p. 144. Complementary examples are sets of machinery. Tractors, with their complements of cultivation and harvesting equipment can be counted assets or measured in dollar value. As the data collected apply to one year only, it is unnecessary to construct price indices. These conditions, (1), (2) and (3), are desirable to ensure that inputs within each category are combined in~propor- tions dictated by the scale line for a subproduction function treating the inputs in category as variable: Y a If (x1, x2....., X“) (4) These input categories should be neither perfect complements or near substitutes relative to each other. This leaves the im- portant economic questions involving input combinations to be answered by the analysis rather than covering them up within categories. (5) Expenses and investments should be kept in separate cate- gories, as the level of returns expected from these two types of inputs are quite different. Cash expenses, as annual inputs, are expected to yield at least a dollar per dollar spent. Investments cover a longer production period than a year; hence, annual return may be lower. Maintenance expenditures and depreciation should be eliminated from all input categories because of the difficulty in preventing duplication. Hence, expected returns to input cate- gories of an investment nature should be high enough to cover in- terest, maintenance, taxes and depreciation. All factors affecting the gross income cannot be adequately covered in a study such as this. Weather is uncontrollable and 10 managerial ability, as an input, at the present state of knowledge, is immeasurable. Frank Knight2 pointed out that our ability to make inferences depends on the existence of constant modes of be- havior (with a known standard deviation from the mean). As the relevant variables are often too numerous for our limited finite human minds, it is necessary to classify them into a number of groups which exhibit similar behavior in certain respects. Even this simplification of the problem is insufficient as we cannot make an exhaustive classification and we have to fall back on con- sistency of behavior or theory of probability so that thinking can be ordered intelligently.' Every effort was therefore made to classify the studied variables into homogeneous groups. The un- studied variables such as weather and managerial ability are as- sumed to have a normal and random distribution with respect to their effect on the dependent variable. Fitting the Data to the Cobb-Douglas Function The fitting of farm input-output data, in the categories developed, enables estimates of marginal value products to be de- termined. The function developed by Cobb and Douglas,3 later re- vised by Douglas4 is the type used in this study. 2Frank E. Knight, Risk Uncertainty and Profit (Boston and New York: Houghton Mifflin Co., 1921), Chap. VII, pp. 197-232. 3Charles W. Cobb and Paul H. Douglas, "A Theory of Produc- tion," The American Economic Review, Supplement, XVIII (March 1928), pp. 136-163. 4Paul H. Douglas, "Are There Laws of Production?" The American Economic Review, XXXVIII, No. 1 (March 1948), pp. 1-41. ll bl b2 bn (3) Y 8 8X1 x2 eeeexn This is a cross product equation enabling the interdepend- encies of the variable inputs to be demonstrated. The function is mainly used to fit gross categories of inputs, as is required by this study. It is often found to be less useful in analyzing single inputs such as required in a soil and fertilizer or a feed and hog output study. The function is linear in the logarithms and becomes: (4) log Y = log a + b1 log X1 + b2 log X2 + ....bn log Xn It is simple to fit to the data by least squares regression. In this study this was accomplished with an electronic computer. Once a fit has been obtained it is easy to manipulate and determine the marginal productivities. The exponents (b1 '8) in the equation are the elasticities of the independent variables (X1 's) with respect to the dependent variable (Y), in this case gross income. The value of these ex— ponents indicates the percentage change in gross income associated with a one percent change in the respective input category, all other inputs held constant. The constant 'a' is the intercept with the Y axis. The marginal productivities of the input categories (Xi) may be calculated directly from the exponents by the formula: b9 i 1 xi (5) MVP A where Y , the estimated gross income, is the antilor of low Y in equation (4) and X1 is the quantity of the innut under con- Sidelnatinn (i = 1, 000‘ n). 5 I I I O I Cobb and Douglas originally imposed the restriction of forcinw the sum of the exponents to equal one. This was equivalent to assuming constant returns to scale. Later this was relaxed and the sum of the exponents was not forced to equal one, permitting increasing, decreasing or constant returns to scale to be 6 reflected. If n b. 1 I: 1‘< ' i = 1 decreasing returns to scale are exhibited, if increasins returns to scale are exhibited, and if n z b,=1 1 i = 1 constant returns to scale are exhibited. The estimated re"ression coefficients (bi's) are constant over the entire function. This assumntion means that the unmodified Cobb-Douglas function can only be used in certain cases where con- stant elasticity of the function can be presumed to exist. It also imnoses the limitation of the inability to handle more than 5Char1es W. Cobb and Paul H. Douglas, 22. cit. 6Paul H. Douglas, 22. ci . 13 one stage of production for any given variable at a time (see Figure 2a). It was suggested that this may not be serious for the data under consideration, as it was believed that these farms were operating in stage II for all single input categories, i.e., where diminishing marginal returns are experienced. The optimum combination of resources can be achieved only in stage II for all variable inputs as a group. Though, strictly speaking, it is irrational to operate within the range of increasing or negative marginal returns, it was later found that the farms were operating in stage II for each input, but in stage I for total inputs. The function is symmetrical (see Figure 2b), with iso Product contour lines becoming asymptotic to the vertical and hori- zontal axes. This implies an unlimited range in which the propor- tions of two inputs can be varied to produce a given output. Fbr example, in the labor machinery dimension, the form of the function indicates that a fixed amount of labor is capable of handling an unlimited quantity of machinery if one were willing to extrapolate beyond the range of any set of observable data. Such extrapola- tions, obviously, would be both impracticable and professionally dangerous. It is feasible that some production would be forth- coming with no investment in machinery, all the work being accom- plished by hand. H. 0. Carter7 has suggested modifications to destroy the constant elasticity and symmetry aspects of the Cobb- 711. 0. Carter, "Modifications of the Cobb-Douglas Function to destroy constant elasticity and symmetry," Resource Productivity, Returns to Scale and Farm Size (Heady, Johnson and Hardin, Iowa State College Press, 1956). pp. 168-174. 14 0 V I I 1 W ' 1 I - ' r‘ x1 X2 X3, '°" X Figure 2a. The Cobb-Douglas production function illustrating decreasing returns to scale only. n o ‘ V 1 m w v V V T Figure 2b. The Cobb-Douglas production surface illustrating symmetrical asymptotic product contours, with straight line expansion paths. 15 Douglas function. The constant symmetry limitation dictates that any expansion path is a straight line cutting all iso product contour lines in the input dimension at the same angle, and passing through the origin. (See Figure 2b, with expansion paths 0A and OB.) Again in the case of labor and machinery this may not be true. As machinery is added, the rate of substitution of machinery for labor would be expected to be quite high at first and then de- crease, hence a curved expansion path could result. However, the advantages of the Cobb-Douglas function with its ease of computation and simplicity outweigh its disadvantages for the purpose of this study. The assumption of constant elas- ticity of the regression coefficients and all that that implies must be kept in mind. The unexplained residuals must be assumed to be normally and randomly distributed with respect to the inde- pendent variables as the logarithmic transformation of the variable inputs presumes a substantial degree of normality of the distribu- tion of the errors in the logarithmic data. As already noted in the introduction, the continuous func- tion analysis of a group of farms having widely different enter- prises requires more time than available for this study.8 Purposive Sampling The reliability of the estimates of the bi's can be deter- mined from the equation:9 8Christoph Beringer, 22. cit. 9Mordecai Ezekiel, Methods of Correlation Anal sis, ’ (Second Edition, New York: John Wiley and Sons Inc., 1939,, p. 502. 16 2'02 {bx ‘ nd’x2(1-R§ i i 1(X1....Xh, Xj....Xn)) There: 202 is the sum of the squared unexplained residuals. (Try to minimize to reduce drbx ) 1 N is the sample number. (Try to maximize to reduce {bx ) 1 (X1 is the variance of Xi. (Try to maximize to reduce ‘Bx ) i R: is the percentage of variance in X, i(Xl....Xh, X3....Xn) explained by the other studied variables. (Try to minimize to re- duce {b "1 Hence, it is necessary to obtain observations of the studied variables over as great an area as reasonable of the production surface; otherwise the estimations of the b '5, and therefore the i marginal value products, are liable to have a large error, unless a very large number of observations are made. Purposive sampling is designed to try to overcome this difficulty of reducing the number of observations necessary and to bring studies of this nature within the realm of economic possibility.10 Farms are se- lected having wide quantity variations of the studied input cate- gories with as little correlation as possible among these categories. This means that imperfectly adjusted farms with respect to the input categories should be included in the sample. 10This is a question of weighing up the marginal utility or accuracy of the study with the marginal cost. 17 The unstudied variables, such as weather and managerial ability should be minimized as to number and variance with random and normal distribution with respect to the studied variables to prevent any bias in the estimation of the b 's. Minimizing the i unexplained residuals was accomplished by choosing a group of relatively homogeneous farms having the same inherent productive capacity, i.e., the same soil type with similar climatic conditions, this means limited geographic range. Variations are assumed to be randomly and normally distributed. In this study only purely cash crop farms, or as nearly pure as possible, were observed; live- stock enterprises were carefully excluded from the data by avoiding such farms or by eliminating the livestock enterprise through ac- counting techniques. All farms should be using the same range of technology and the same technology for a given combination of inputs. The quality of the inputs in each input category should be the same and they should be combined in the best possible proportions. If the conditions in these last two paragraphs are success- fully met, we can assume all these farms are operating on the same production surface and that the interfirm, intrafirm problem pointed out by Bronfenbrenner11 does not apply. 11Martin Bronfenbrenner, "Production Functions: Cobb-Douglas, Interfirm, Intrafirm," Econometrics XII, No. 1 (January 1944), pp. 35-44. CHAPTER III SAMPLING PROCEDURE AND MEASUREMENT TECHNIQUES The Sample Strong effort was made to select farms which were homo- geneous with respect to the non-studied variables such as weather, type of production, technology and managerial ability, and which were non-homogeneous with respect to the proportions and quantities of the studied variables. This was in accordance with the reason- ing in the previous chapter. Table I gives detailed data for the individual farms in the sample. (1) Type of farming was restricted to cash crop with the absence, or absolute minimum, of livestock. All these farms grew white pea beans, wheat and sugar beets, with some growing smaller acreages of oats, corn, barley, soybeans and alfalfa. Restricting the sample to farms growing sugar beets eliminated a large propor- tion of those growing cash crops. Otherwise the cropping is fairly representative for cash crop farming in the thumb area of Michigan. The percentages of tillable crop land, by crops, in the sample was: White pea beans 44.1% Wheat 21 .096 Sugar beets 20.0% Oats 5.2% Corn 4.9% Barley 2.7% Soybeans 1.2% Alfalfa 0.5% Other 0.4% 19 .ueaaulo osob case one once: .ouaesu as» we oupouaeuoahdso so: use NA .02 sash. ”fined Onucn anew ahead vnnoo o¢omv On.Nn ace ovomw an Oahu comm m¢bv “one Omaha nuObH OO.NN own auaom on OnON oonh memo Oanw Nunon Dacha oo.vn mnv awnwn GN 06¢ Ombo coon nnom mcuwu OACmH DN.~N nfid nmwmn an OONH Donn mwnv dowfl modmfl abomd DN.DN own unflafl 5N amen Chub ank mm¢b nmflhv Cmn¢N OO.hN 50¢ wflbot 0N com Oahu bnon moan nvomq name nm.hn and .anwn 0N ocmm OOOOA w¢nvn G¢on Noses mucon OO.¢O haw whwmb VN con o¢on amen fined wchH oawv OO.N~ and m¢nm nN 06mm omen anon nwmu wanna nevus OO.nH non nbvmu NN ODN¢ ombv nnhd OOON mflwmd Giana whofln and nnmud MN con Oman Hdhd bond onbnn Gonna ab.Nn ova ambwu ON Oahu canon flwbb NnnN mwvon OOnmn oooon va NNmNn ad chums ovow heme nan» thnfl OGkaN ocoaN «an HONOV mu onus Gown onfiv wflwu NNuOH nvond nwocn n0 mabmu ha can Chop mnwn hmnn Annnw nabbn Oooun cad «noon 0n moan comm ”ecu «was dmoua bbmb Db.OA ch @000 um nbmu cane mafia nub» wanna nvmuw oo.oq aom Once" VA OBOH Guam thv nmom whomfl nwcnfl Oflomn now aOhoH nu 000 Onwm naON fivtn Ohm wab cm.a O¢H m¢oa «no I come omon amen comma nvmnn coonn and Hnbnn an I Donn nnmn oNnN mnDau O¢DOA oo.o~ wbn wanna On can Gena avwd Nana Gamma anew ocoflfi co" bwovn a O¢¢ OO¢Q uwnv bnmfl mwmw unwmd econu aha Decca m ow Chou bme nOOn mbnm gone Broad ob waned 5 Cum 00mm mafia Dvflu ncbfld Gama Gaodfi ”a macaw o Omv onmb mama nbNN finanw nnncn ocovn and Canon 0 macs OODD HNO¢ «ban ocbfln avocd On.an vHN OnNnn ¢ Oflnu Gamma uwflo Dean nbfinn Ontcn 09.nw dun mvfinn n 009 owww m¢¢n doc» nmnNH Onbsu oc.m~ "AN amnmn N GAG Onwb Odom was» annON nnflbu ch.H~ and wonON M o o o o o o o unusua0>aH scenauobsn ouaaoam ousaoum nonsense easanusoaxw aselume>sn asoEunoasH eavso: eoao< oaoosH nonlsz saoo a cause haesuaosx nose fiasco aouunueaeh owesqssn hhosusoel nonla onnsnnue nacho lash fldmxdm HEB 2H mzmsh HZOIHBMH=H HEB xbmk GNBOQAAGU 19¢: AdOHmHmzfl BO hmomitted the fit was improved still further. (r2 = .8912) Actual Gross Income (Thousands of Dollars) 50 80,, I I. I 70- I / / I . I 604 ,’ I I. .I ’I 0 50a 1’ . 0/ I I ‘I I 40‘ ,’ / x I I I 30 4 ’I I / e I I e v’ 20' 0”, g - )‘.. . vfic’._ ”/. . 10‘ ’. ’. O I T I I I l w t ' ' r f T *1 F V T *3 .l .2 .3 .4 .5 .6 .7 .8 .9 1.0 1.1 1.2 1.31.4 1.5 1.61.? 1.8 Units of Limiting Factor Figure 3. Relationship between gross income and units of limiting factor on the farms in the sample. 51 The standard units of the limiting factors, used in this analysis, with their respective expected returns, or minimum charges, are presented in Table IV. TABLE IV THE "STANDARD UNITS" OF THE LIMITING FACTORS USED IN THE FUNCTIONS ASSUMING PERFECT COMPLEMENTARITY OF THE INPUT CATEGORIES, 'ITH THEIR.MINIMUM EXPECTED RETURNS Input "Standard Unit" Expected Expected Returns Category of Input Returns9 girufigtz::a531;5§:' of Limiting Factors Land 233.3 T.A. 835/14. 38,165.5 Labor 22.275 months 3225/honth 55,011.9 Machinery investment $17,084 30 percent $5,125.2 Drainage investment $23,007 10 percent 32,300.? Fertilizer expenses 33,210 106 percent $3,402.6 Other crop expenses $4,458 106 percent $4,725.5 The estimating equation is leg Y = log x + b log (units of limiting factor). If the limiting factor is one, then log A log Y = 4.561792 + 1.049541 x O or log 9 -.- 4.561792 and log 9 a $36,457. The productivity coefficients were then calculated to be: Land $68.11 per tillable acre Labor $571.83 per month Machinery investment .7522 per dollar 9Refer to p. 41. 52 Fertilizer expenses 3.4667 per dollar Other crop expenses 2.7930 per dollar Drainage investment .4358 per dollar These estimates are considerably higher than those deter- mined from the normal Cobb-Douglas analyses due to the same excess return being credited to each estimated AVP or MVP in turn, i.e., if a mistake is made in estimating one, the same error will be reflected in each of the other estimates. Consistent under- or overestimation of the AVP's or MVP's by this residual method of computation can thus occur with all the estimates being biased in the same direction. This is a general characteristic of residual computation of AVP's and MVP's which can occur in farm accounting, linear programming and budgeting unless care is taken. The unreliability of those estimated MVP's was one reason for fitting the next function even though the ability of the two functions to predict gross income was not significantly different. The Final FUnction It was now becoming apparent that land and drainage invest- ment, in the area from which this sample was taken, were almost jperfect complements. Hence, as with the regression analysis as- suming perfect complementarity, the number of units of limiting factor of either land or drainage, measured in terms of the geometric mean quantities of either, was set up as one variable input (X2). Labor (X3) and machinery investment (X4) were left as they were, as the MVP of these input categories are of particular interest to both farm management men and policy makers and it appeared that 53 reliable estimates of their MVP‘s were obtainable. Current fer— tilizer and crop expenses were lumped together as one input (X5), as it appeared that no headway was being made in obtaining a reli- able regression coefficient for either alone. Crap storage in- vestment-was omitted because of the unreliability of the regression coefficient; hence, the return to the other inputs may, but do not necessarily, as the constant turned out to be slightly larger, reflect some of the returns to crop storage. The estimated bi's and their standard errors were found to be: Units of limiting factor (either land or drainage investment) b .435713 I .145849 b Labor .275044 .t .113725 Hachinery investment b .204850 1 .123718 Current fertilizer and crop expenses b3 .170704 1 .136325 More reliance could now be placed on the estimates of the regression coefficients and hence also the resulting marginal value productivities. The estimated bi's were now different from zero at levels of significance of one percent for the limiting factor (b2), 3 percent for labor (b3). 12 percent for machinery invest- ment (b4) and 23 percent for current fertilizer and crap expenses (b5). The sum of the bi.. was 1.08631, again indicating increas- ing returns to scale. The marginal value products were then computed as in Table v e 54 TABLE V THE MARGINAL VALUE PRODUCTIVITIES OF THE GEOMETRIC MEAN QUANTITIES or INPUTS USED ON THIRTY CASH CROP FARMS IN THE SAGINAw VALLEY AND THUMB AREA OF MICHIGAN, 1957. (DERIVED FROM THE FINAL PRODUCTION FUNCTION, IHICH TREATED LAND AND DRAINAGE INVEs'nsNT As PERFECT COWLEMENTS) Geometric Mean MVP Input Category Quantity of Input (dollars) X2 Limiting factor .88038 10,507.05 X2 in terms of drained land 193 T.A. 54.45 X3 Labor 19 months 306.87 x4 Machinery investment $14,654 .2968 X5 Current fertilizer and crop expenses $6,609 .5484 As it was assumed that land and drainage were perfect com- plements, the MVP of limiting factor (X2) now represents the marginal return to adequately drained land. This was recomputed to be $54.45 per drained tillable acre. It is of interest to note that the MVP for undrained land, from the first function fitted, was computed to be $24.71 per tillable acre. The returns to average drainage investment per tillable acre was computed to be $31.00, using an MVP for drainage investment of 31 percent. The sum of these two, representing total MVP of a drained tillable acre, is $55.71, which is almost the same as the $54.45 per drained tillable acre computed from this final function. The log of the geometric mean gross income (log Q) was 4.327391 with a standard error of estimate §.of .078368, i.e., the 55 geometric mean estimated gross income would be expected to fall between $17,743 and $25,454 in 68.27 percent of the sample. Log ‘ was 2.494105. The multiple correlation coefficient (R) was .95919 which would be expected to be as high as this in 5 percent of the cases in a similarly drawn sample if the true (R) was .93. The coefficient of determination (R2) was .92. The estimated marginal value productivity of current ferti- lizer and crop expenses still appeared low. As these inputs were highly correlated with other inputs some of the returns may still be reflected in overestimated MVP's of these other inputs. Fbr instance it pays to apply more fertilizer to adequately drained land than undrained land as responses are less risky. Hence an overestimate in the MVP to drainage investment may result. In 1957 it is doubtful whether a normal response to fertilizer was in fact obtained. The bean crap in particular was adversely affected by the weather. As beans occupy 44 percent of the acreage of the sample this would mean a large reduction in response to fertilizer applications. Trials conducted by Michigan Agricultural Experi- ment Station on similar soils in 195710 showed economic responses in the cases of wheat and corn at low levels of fertilizer appli- cation only. Many of the farmers in the sample were using the accepted full fertilizing rates and hence it may be suspected that 1OJ. F. Davis, L. S. Robertson and I. B. Sundquist, unpub- lished results from "Fertilizer Input-Output Studies, 1957," con- ducted cooperatively by the Departments of Soil Science and Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University. 56 they were in fact not obtaining an economic response of at least a dollar per dollar expense at the margin. The input categories of land, labor, machinery investment and drainage investment were quite highly correlated with the crop expenses category. Hence judgment must be used in interpreting the results. The MVP of machinery investment possibly also re- flects some of the returns to fuel costs, which was a large item in the crop expense category. This could cause overestimation of the MVP of machinery investment with corresponding underestimation of the MVP of current crop and fertilizer expenses. The estimated regression coefficients were compared with the regression coefficients necessary to yield minimum expected returns.11 These are presented in the following table. TABLE VI COMPARISON OF THE ESTIMATED bi's AND THE bi's NECESSARY TO YIELD MINIMUM MARGINAL VALUE PRODUCTS, FINAL FUNCTION ' hi to Yield b1 Estimated b1 Estimated bi. Minimum Difference df’ Returns b2 .435713 .145849 .457321 -.021608 b3 .275044 .113725 .201666 .073378 b4 .204850 .123718 .241579 -.036729 11See p. 41. 57 The regression coefficients were almost identical in the case of drained land. Those for labor and machinery investment were not significantly different. However, the regression coeffi- cient for current fertilizer and crop expense (b5) was significantly different, probably due to the inclusion of the fertilizer expense in this input category. The unexplained residuals were plotted against estimated gross income. The distribution appeared to be normal and random. Complementarity of the Inputs To test the hypothesis that the input categories, used in the limiting factor production functions, are better complements than can be fitted with a Cobb-Douglas function, a test was set up to compare the unexplained residuals of these functions with those of the first and final Cobb-Douglas functions. The percentage of (the variance in Y minus the variance explained by the restrictions of the production function) explained by the analysis is given by: 2 1: u2 R s _2 Z(Y—Y) 3:5 I! where: I u2 is the sum of the squared unexplained residuals (Y-Y), Y is the actual gross income, I is the mean, n is the number in the sample (30) and m is the number of restrictions (2 in the cases of the limiting factor functions, 9 for the first and 5 for the last Cobb-Douglas functions). 58 (a) First Cobb-Douglas function, R2 - .799614 (b) Final Cobb-Douglas function, R2 - .948745 (c) Limiting factor function in natural numbers, R2 2 .748333 (d) Limiting factor function in logarithms, R2 = .8848. It was then hypothesized that there was no difference be- tween the Rz's. These percentages were tested by means of a chi square test.12 R2 :z'z = l 737 a difference significant at be- (c) and (d) ' ’ tween the 10 percent and 25 percent levels. 2 2 . R (c) and (b) ‘X = 3.4607, a difference significant at be- tween the 5 percent and 10 percent levels. 2 2 . R (b) and (d) x = .69206, indicating no significant dif- ference between these functions at between the 50 percent and 75 percent levels. This means that the limiting factor function, expressed in logarithms (page 49) is not a significantly poor predictor of gross income than the Cobb-Douglas function. The advantage of the final Cobb-Douglas function is its ability to give reliable estimated MVP's as Opposed to the unreliable residual method of computing them from the previous function. Managerial Ability The farmers in the sample were rated from 0-10 according to an informal assessment of their managerial ability made during 12C. Eisenhart, M. W. Hastay and W. A. Wallis, Techniques of Statistical Analysis (First edition, McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc., 1947), pp. 255-257, especially expression (16), page 257. 59 the interview. The profit motive was taken as the basis of the assessment but the farm records were ignored while the rating was being made. Assessments were made of their I.Q. together with their understanding, and use of, simple economic theory as applied to farming and their apparent ability to rationalize and come to decisions. This rating was then correlated with the percentage of estimated gross income actually achieved.13 First Cobb-Douglas function r = .38318 r2 = .1468? Final Cobb-Douglas function r = .37660 2 r = .14183 The correlations were low, but nevertheless significantly different from zero, fourteen percent of the variation in unex- plained residuals being associated with this measure of managerial ability. The correlation has probably been reduced due to lowering gross income, by the accounting procedure, for farmers growing seed crops. These farmers generally were assessed as having above average managerial ability. Share renting was not common but may have been correlated with a lower managerial rating, thus affecting the correlation of gross income and managerial ability as yields on share rented land were generally lower than on owner occupied land. If this is a reasonable assessment of managerial ability it would indicate that in this area difference in managerial ability 13 Actual gross income Estimated gross income «9M 60 is not a major factor to be considered, i.e., management on these farms is a relatively simple matter or, of course, the level of management was relatively uniform and did not vary so greatly from farm to farm. The larger proportion of the unexplained residuals must be due to other unstudied variables such as weather, sug- gesting that these are more important factors than management. Weather can influence gross income quite considerably, particularly in relation to the bean crop. CHAPTER V EVALUATION It must be stressed that these results apply only within the conditions of the study, the range of data collected and with the conditions of weather, price and state of knowledge existing in that area in 1957. Land and Investment in Drainage; Land and investment in drainage are considered concurrently as their complementary nature has been demonstrated. This was par- ticularly so in the final Cobb-Douglas regression analysis because of the reliability of the estimated regression coefficient from which the estimate of the marginal value productivity of drained land was obtained. 1 Farmers had good reason to be concerned with the high sale Value of land, whether drained or undrained, in this area. Un- drained land was estimated to be yielding less than expected returns and returns to drained land almost covered expected returns. It is pr Obable that the drainage part of the investment in drained land, in 1957, was yielding a more than adequate return with under re- co“Finest as regards the investment in the raw land. Reference to Table X, in Appendix A, indicates that the marginal value productivity of land tends to fall as farm size in“greases. The proportion of land in the mix of the input categories 61 62 tends to increase as farm size increases and this would result in the falling MVP for land. However, it does not fall rapidly, in fact the graph of gross income plotted against tillable acres is almost a straight line. The return to drainage investment appears to be similar irrespective of farm size.1 The importance of adequate drainage on these farms is ob- vious and this is supported by the estimated return of 30 percent on investment in 1957. Farmers estimate that a general increase in yield of 50 percent, or better, results from tile drainage.2 1957 was a favorable year as regards returns to drainage invest- ment, so that a study should be extended over a number of years to obtain a more generally acceptable figure. It would be ex- pected that the marginal return to 100 percent adequately drained farms would not be significantly different from minimum expected returns. If the estimated returns are much higher in average seasons it would indicate that it may pay farmers to tile drain their land at even closer intervals than the present accepted standard. As such a high return to drainage has been estimated from farms having on the average 80 percent of their tillable acres adequately drained, it suggests further investigation in this direction may be worthwhile. 1The estimated returns to drainage investment are higher in the case of some of the 200-300 acre farms (see Table X, Appendix A). This is due to a lower percentage of the land being drained on these farms. 2C. R. Hoglund, Managerial Decisions in Organizinggand Operating a Farm, Ag. Econ. Bull. No. 625, p. 6. Department of Agricultural Economics and the Agricultural Experiment Station, Michigan State University, September 28, 1955. 63 Labor The estimate of the regression coefficient for labor in the final regression equation was highly reliable, but not signifi- cantly different from the regression coefficient required to yield minimum expected returns. Reference to Table VII shows that the resultant estimate of the MVP for labor was higher than those ob- tained in other studies, particularly those involving livestock. The reliability of the estimate of the b for labor in this study 1 gives greater confidence to the MVP estimate for labor. It is not surprising that farms in this area are moving out of dairying and concentrating on cash crop production. The total derivative to one month of labor was computed to be 31,297; this is the MVP of one month of labor in the geometric mean organization plus the sum of the MVP's of the increases in the other input categories associated with one month of labor. This result is higher than the average gross income per man month, in a report on this area,3 of between 8598 and $1,007 for 1957. This is largely due to (l) the method of measuring the input of labor, (2) the fact that the farms in the area report included a proportion of dairy farms which would have a lower gross income per man month than cash crap farms, and (3) increasing returns to scale. 3F'arming Today, Area 8 report, 1958. CoOperative Extension Service, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State Uni- versity. 64 TABLE VII REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS AND MARGINAL VALUE PRODUCTIVITIES OF ONE MONTH OF LABOR, IN VARIOUS FARMING AREAS, OBTAINED IN RECENT STUDIES Total Derivative MVP b 5' b to One Month of Study i i (dollars) , Labor (dollars) 1 Almont Township .160 .119 91.24 682.43 Michigan 1953 2 Burnside Township .186‘ .096’ 123.42‘ 816.19‘ Michigan 1953 3 N W Illinois, 1950 .006 .084 8.40 1334.00 (Hog enterprise) per hour ‘ 4 N W Illinois, 1950 .222 .141 137.4 694.00 (Dairy enterprise) per hour 5 N W Illinois, 1950 .129 .166 143.6 1206.00 (Crop enterprise) per hour 6 Ogemaw-Arenac Co., .382’ .301‘ 198.25‘ 660.03' Mich. 1953 (Beef enterprise) 7 Ogemaw-Arenac Co., .414‘ .154' 148,7’ 428.90‘ Mich. 1953 (Processed milk farms) 8 089-8.-”enac Gas, e277 e113 123e96 594.61 Mich. 1953 ~ (Fluid milk farms) 9 Soil 3. South Cen. .076 .296 40.79 705.57 Mich. 1953 (Dairy enterprise) 10 Soil P4 Southern Mich.-.034 .528 -21.43 599.91 1953 (Dairy enterprise) 11 Soil P. SO. Cen. Mich. .434 .237 262.08 798.43 1953 (Dairy enterprise) . 12 Soil 0. 30. Gem. Mich. .519 .299 304.9 797.26 1953 (Dairy enterprise) « 13 Ingham Co., Mich. 1952 .042 .130 30.19 787.01 (Dairy enterprise) This study .275 .124 306.87 1279.00 .Unreliable because of high intercorrelation with machinery investment. 65 The method of estimating labor input was a little more rigorous than most previous studies in that no account was taken of time spent on the farm between seasons. It was assumed that these Operators then had the Opportunity to take off the farm em- ployment. This is usually available during the winter when average weekly earnings should be possible of $86-87 per week or 3350 per month.4 All family labor was reduced to average man month equi- valents. Even though returns to labor are relatively high, there is room for improvement. The most obvious being reduction in labor requirements for hoeing and singling sugar beets. The mechanical thinner was introduced into this area around 1950, at that time studies showed a 10 percent reduction in crop yield due to mechanical thinning which more than offset the 40 percent decrease in labor costs for hoeing.5 Since then improvements in the thinners and techniques of using them have taken place and more recent studies6 by the sugar beet companies in that area have not shown significant differences in yields due to mechanical thinning; on the contrary, frequently the yield has been improved ‘Nichi an Labor Market, Vol. XII, No. 4 (April 1957). and Vol. XIII, No. 4 (April 1958). Published by Michigan Employment Security Commission, 7310 woodward Avenue, Detroit 2, Michigan. 5George N. French, A Report on Tests of Mechanical weeding and Thinning Equipment in Michiggg and The Extent of Sprigg Mechanization in the Eastern Beet Areaj 1951. Proceedings of the American Society of Sugar Beet Technologists, 1952, pp. 586-592. 6Monitor Sugar Beet Company, Mechanical Thinning of Sugar Beets,gl955. The Monitor Sugar Beet Co., Bay City, Michigan. 66 due to timeliness of the operation. These 1955 studies did not always show great reductions in labor requirements; however, it is generally suggested that a 50 percent reduction in labor require- ments for thinning and hoeing the sugar beets would result.7 Mexican labor used for hoeing costs farmers 3170 to 8200 per month, if they were obtaining a return of $306 for the marginal month of labor it would support their perseverance with hand labor. Other methods of reducing labor requirements during this period are now being investigated. The new approach is to obtain a more even stand of plants by using monogerm seed, better placement drills and obtaining ideal seed bed conditions. Modern machinery and new techniques have reduced sowing time considerably. .Unfortunately, this has resulted in all the sugar beets being ready for hoeing at the same time. In an area where custom labor is limited it is a case of "first come, first served." Hence, reduction of the total Mexican laborers force employed by the sugar beet companies in the Thumb area is not immediately likely. The shortening of the sugar beet thinning season could mean these Mexicans being partially unemployed between hoeings, in which case a higher wage rate for hoeing might be de- manded. Mechanical thinning would then appear a more attractive proposition. It should also be noted that the mechanical thinner —__ 7c. R. Hoglund and K. T. wright, Estimated Labor Require- ggpts for Sggar Beet Productions in Michigan, 9.9 ton_yield, Four Methods of Production. Adapted from Michigan Circular Bulletin ."—-—_ 215, Uune 1949. 67 does enable a partial thinning of the stand at a critical stage when hand labor is not immediately available. Other opportunities for improving labor efficiency would be at the later peak period of harvesting. Materials handling is a relatively recent field of study which may provide answers to this end of the problem. The techniques of minimum tillage, which is now a recog- nized practice on these farms, have enabled substantial reductions in cultivation requirements so that farmers can now cope with what were once time consuming jobs. Modern machinery with its high work output has been of great assistance in this respect. The MVP of labor tends to increase with increase in farm size. This might be expected from the evidence of increasing returns to scale, also as the number of tillable acres per man month tends to increase with farm size. It is interesting to note that these returns are significantly higher on the 130-150 acre, family size, holdings than the small, 70-100 acre holdings; but returns do not increase so rapidly on the larger farms. This might suggest that the 130-150 acre holding is a minimum size in order to employ fully the operator's and family labor, and provide adequate returns to that labor. Few farmers employed full time labor. Those that did, provided some incentive to keep the workers on the farm. They were all provided with rent free housing and most of them had some opportunity to augment their income by crepping a few acres of their own accord, using their employer's machinery at a nominal charge. 68 Machinery This area is very highly mechanized which has assisted in the reduction of labor requirements and led to an improvement in the returns to labor. Reference to Table VIII indicates some of the substitution of machinery for labor in this area during the past twenty years. It should be pointed out that more machinery and less labor were spread over a larger acreage, as the average farm size in the reports on this area,8 from which Table VIII was derived, increased from 102 acres in 1935 to 149 acres in 1956. The b1 for machinery investment is not significantly dif- ferent from that necessary to yield minimum returns. However, the returns appear lower on the small farms suggesting their over- investment in machinery, or underinvestment in respect of land. Machinery investment per tillable acre decreases with increase in farm size. The Opportunities on these small farms to reduce their investment in machinery are not as great as might first be thought. The real difficulty is that the bean crop needs immediate harvest- ing during a critical period; hence, the bean harvester or combine must be immediately available. As already pointed out, modern methods of sowing have resulted in most of the crop, in this area, being ready for harvesting at the same time, so that the neighbors' or the custom combine may not be available and the crop consequently lost. This position has not been improved by the persistent use of bean varieties which mature at the same time. Grain and sugar 8Farmin Toda , Area 8 report, 1935-56, 93. cit. 69 TABLE VIII mm or MEN AND MACHINERY INVESTMENT PER 100 TILLABLE ACRES, 1935-1956, mm s, MICHIGAN9 Year Number Deflated Machinery of Men Investment 1937-41 = 100 1935 1.96 81200 36 1.79 1212 37 1.73 1344 38 1.76 1563 39 1.65 1649 40 1.60 1716 41 1.52 1858 42 1.57 2042 43 1.36 2033 44 1.30 1936 45 1.33 2057 46 1.36 2050 47 1.34 1980 48 1.32 2053 49 1.37 2395 50 1.38 2691 51 1.33 2722 52 1.28 2914 53 1.23 2982 54 1.23 2991 55 1.11 2978 56 1.07 2930 beet harvest is spread over a longer period enabling outside as- sistance to be possible. An alternative is cooperative machine ownership. Only one real case of this was met on the farms visited. Here, four farms, each of about 120 acres, c00peratively owned a combine, a bean harvester and a sugar beet harvester. Generally, more friendships have been broken than made in cooperative ownership 9Area 8 is cash crop and dairy farming in the Saginaw Valley and Northern Thumb areas of Michigan. 70 of harvesting equipment. However, in this case, the success of the venture can be judged from a five year history of almost per- fect harmony. The basis was a properly drawn up agreement whereby expenses were paid on a crop proportion basis and from a central fund raised by custom work with this machinery. Fuel and oil were provided by the farmer concerned and labor assistance was paid for on a regular hourly basis. In the case of beans, only twenty acres could be harvested at one time by any one farmer; each had to take his turn. Many farms appeared to have more tractors than necessary. All farms had two tractors and some small farms even had three. The reason given for this was ease of Operation. The idea was to have a large high horsepowered tractor for the heavy work of ploughing and preparing a seed bed, etc., and a light, more maneuverable tractor for row-crop work. This allowed the small tractor to be hitched up with inter-row cultivation equipment throughout the season, leaving the larger one free for other work and thus avoiding the time consuming job of attaching and unat- taching equipment. The essence of farming in this area appeared to be to have the equipment to get the job done as quickly and as efficiently as possible because of the critical periods of crop sowing, growth and maturity. Pride of possession also seemed to be a factor, as many small farms had invested in overly large combines. 71 Fertilizer Expenditure The estimated bi for fertilizer expense had a high standard error which made the estimate of the MVP unreliable. Reasons have already been given for suspecting that returns to the fer- tilizer input were, in fact, less than a dollar for a dollar in 1957. Also, the MVP may be underestimated with corresponding overestimates in the MVP's of land and drainage investment. Nothing more will be added here, except that fertilizer input-output studies in this area10 have indicated that more than a dollar re- turn per dollar invested is obtained in average years with the generally accepted levels of fertilizer application. Table IX indicates the variation in quantities of fertilizers applied to the three main crops on the farms in the sample in 1957. It appeared that wheat was most frequently over fertilized particularly with nitrogen and this was borne out by observations of the farmers concerned. The breeding of a short, stiff-strawed wheat for this area is urgently required. Many farmers were using more than optimum quantities of nitrogen on sugar beets. Other Current Crop Expenses The estimated b was unreliable reducing the confidence in i the estimate of the MVP for other crop expenses. The estimates 10L. S. Robertson and W. B. Sundquist, An Economic Analysis of Some Controlled Fertilizers Input-Output Experiments in Michigan. Data 1955 and 1956. Unpublished technical bulletin. Michigan Agricultural Experiment Station. 72 TABLE IX RANGE IN QUANTITIES 0F ARTIFICIAL FERTILIZERS APPLIED TO THE THREE MAIN CROPS OF THIRTY SAGINAW VALLEY AND THUMB CASH CROP FfiRMS IN 1957 Pounds of Fertilizer Appliedgper Acre Cro Plant P Nutrient Lowest Highest Suggested 11 Level Level Optimum Rates Sugar Beets N 20 130 40 P205 72 234 80 - 160 K20 72 376 40 — 80 Beans ‘N 0 12 15 P205 0 48 30 - 60 K20 0 48 15 - 30 Wheat N 8 67 16 P205 21 200 48 - 96 K20 21 200 24 - 48 from this study suggest an inefficient use of this input in 1957, with the reservation that some of the return to fuel, in particular, may be reflected in overestimated returns to the machinery invest— ment and labor input categories. Buildings Little confidence can be placed in the estimates of returns to crop storage and machinery storage investments. Other studies 11Fertilizer Recommendations for Michigan Crops, Extension Bulletin 159 (Revised), Oct. 1957. Michigan State University Cooperative Extension Service, p. 16. 73 which have attempted to estimate the regression coefficient of in- vestment in buildings have met with the same difficulty of ade- quately measuring the value of buildings. No observation on the returns to building investment will therefore be made. Increasing:Returns to Scale Since the sum of the bi's was consistently greater than one, and also because of supporting evidence from examination of the data with inputs treated as perfect complements, increasing returns to scale are indicated. Increasing farm size and conse- quent reduction in the number of farms in this area cannot, there- fore, be expected necessarily to reduce overall production. Increasing returns to scale also means that it is impossible to compute a high profit point unless one or more of the input categories are held constant. In any case, extrapolation beyond the range of the data is not advisable. However, as suggested by Kaldor,12 management may eventually prove the limiting factor; this important input, by necessity, was not included in the empirical production function. The Complementarity of the Input Categories The complementary nature of the input categories has been demonstrated, particularly in relation to the inputs of land and 12N. Kaldor, "The Equilibrium of the Firm," Economic Journal, Vol. 44 (1934), pp. 60 ff. 74 drainage investment as shown in the final function. Also, the function assuming perfect complementarity of the inputs, when ex- pressed in logarithms, was not significantly different in its ability to predict gross income than the final function. How- ever, the superiority of the final Cobb-Douglas function is in its ability to produce less biased estimates of the MVP's of the input categories. The simple linear function assuming perfect complementary of the inputs did not provide a good fit as increasing returns to scale were exhibited. If the optimum proportions of inputs had been known and used to discover the limiting factors a better fit may have resulted. This suggests that a linear programming study in this area may prove interesting and worthwhile. Reorganization of a Farm on the Basis of the Estimates It has already been noted that the farms in the sample ap- peared to be fairly well adjusted to conditions existing in 1957. An attempt was made to discover maladjusted farms as this would have increased the reliability of the estimated regression coef- ficients. As this attempt, unfortunately, was not too successful, there are few farms in the sample which can profitably be investi- gated with a view to attaining a much better adjustment. However, one farm.(No. 16) was sufficiently out of adjustment to warrant examinamion and can be used to illustrate the use of this type of analysis for individual farm management advisory purposes. 75 Observations and estimations using the results obtained from this study must be tempered with an appreciation of the limi— tations of the results. This will be kept in mind in the following illustration. Farm No. 16 extends to 296 tillable acres. The cropping in 1957 included 46 acres of wheat, 126 acres of white pea beans and 85 acres of sugar beets. These are all high value crops. Yields in 1957 were lower than normal, largely because of the wet weather conditions. However, only 170 acres had been effectively tile drained. The poor drainage existing on the remainder had certainly contributed to the reduction in yields in 1957 and the yield potential in more normal years. The gross income achieved was 326,019 or 888.00 per acre, whereas the average gross income achieved in the sample was $110.00 per acre. The quantities of inputs used on this farm in 1957 with their estimated marginal value products were: Estimated Estimated Geometric Mean MVP MVP for the Sample Inp“t °““”t1ty (dollars) (dollars) Land 296 TA 25.00 24.06 iLabor 51 months 177.63 306.87 Machinery investment $17,795 .37916 .2968 Drainage investment $21,551 .42721 .3020 Fartilizers and cr0p expense 6 7,425 .75724 .5484 tr; _ 76 It will be assumed that farm size cannot be increased and will remain limited to the 296 acres. Examination of the estimated MVP's shows that the marginal return to labor was lower than average with a higher than average return to machinery investment. This was not surprising in view of the high labor requirement on this farm for hand lifting of the sugar beets. Sixty-five acres were lifted by Mexican hand labor; the remaining 20 acres by custom machine harvesting at $20 per acre. With such a large acreage of sugar beets an investigation into the reduction in labor requirements and other costs by the purchase of a sugar beet harvester seemed in order. It is esti- mated that a reduction of 16 months of Mexican labor could be achieved by the purchase of a mechanical sugar beet harvester costing 83,500. A partial budget would show: Increased costs: Gas, oil, repairs, etc. 3400. Interest on investment @ 6% 210. Depreciation @ 20% 700. 31,310. Reduced costs: 16 months Mexican labor @ 3170/month $2,720. 20 acres custom harvesting @ SZO/acre 3 400. 3,120. Net reduction in annual costs $1,810. This would reduce costs sufficiently to enable the cost of the harvester to be met out of increased profits in two years. 77 If the other inputs remained fixed the effect on the esti- mated MVP's would be: Land 5 23.30 per tillable acre Labor 8242.117 per month Machinery investment .2964 dollar per dollar Drainage investment .3982 " " " Fertilizer and crop expenses .7083 " " " The MVP for labor has been increased considerably with a corresponding reduction in the MVP for machinery investment. Already an improvement in the adjustment has been achieved. A slight re- duction in all the MVP's is noticed, this is due to a slightly lower estimated gross income. The estimated MVP for drainage appeared to be very high, which is not surprising considering the large acreage still requir- ing tile drainage. Adequate drainage of the remainder would cost about 8140 per acre requiring an increased investment of 817,640. A charge of 8 percent to cover interest on investment, depreciation and maintenance would result in increased annual costs of $1,411. It might be expected that under similar conditions existing in 1957, an income of 5110 per acre should be achieved as fertilizer usage was not greatly different from the average. Increased returns would be 86,541, leaving a net increase of 55,130. This should enable repayment of the loan necessary to finance this increased investment within four years. If these two major changes could be financed it would have the following effect on the estimated MVP's of the inputs: 78 Land 8 27.53 per tillable acre Labor $276.99 per month Machinery investment .3391 dollar per dollar Drainage investment .2587 " " " Fertilizer and crop expense .8104 " " " Estimated gross income had increased to $35,248.00. The farm now appears to be in much better adjustment with marginal returns more in line with minimum expected returns. (See page‘4l.) The estimated MVP of drainage had been reduced with sub- stantial increases to the MVP's of the other input categories. This illustrates the reverse effect of the law of diminishing returns on the inputs held constant. Mention has been made of the possibility of increasing returns by increasing the quantity of fertilizer applied to these crops on the now drained land. The estimated MVP for fertilizer and crop expense is less than 51.06 (the suggested minimum return) which implies the higher input of fertilizer would be unprofitable. However, the reliability of this estimated MVP is questionable and outside evidence would support a decision to apply increased quan- tities of fertilizer. Drained land is usually easier to manage and cultivate with fewer hold ups in work than undrained land. Hence, it is quite possible that other current crop expenses, such as gas and machinery repairs, would be reduced, thus tending to offset the suggested in- crease in fertilizer expense. This example illustrates the use of the Cobb-Douglas type of analysis as a guide to advice on the individual farm. It thus complements usual farm management methods in helping to delimit 79 general weaknesses in the farm business. The details required for making the ultimate decision being achieved by such practices as partial budgeting. This particular example also illustrates, in a simple way, the real advantage of being able to allocate a definite return to each of the machinery investment and labor input categories, thus giving a more objective basis for advice than labor efficiency measured in terms of productive work units per man. The high profit point was then calculated for this farm with acreage assumed fixed at 296 acres. Unless one or more of the input categories are held constant a high profit point cannot be calculated as the sum of the bi's is greater than one, i.e., increasing returns to scale. At the high profit point (using the final Cobb-Douglas function) estimated gross income is $45,511. The land is now as- sumed to be fully drained, the increased investment necessary has already been computed. It was then computed that the optimum organization would mean altering the quantities of the other inputs to: Labor 52 months Machinery investment 531,076. Fertilizer and other expenses 3 7,329. After draining the remaining acreage the only input that appears to need radical change from the quantities used in 1957 is that of machinery investment. The need for a sugar beet harvester has already been examined. The other item of equipment lacking on this farm is a combine. A bean harvester is already owned but a spike—tooth combine capable of threshing beans would be an asset 80 in view of the large acreage of beans which must be harvested quickly at a critical period. A new twelve foot self-propelled combine, of the type suggested, would cost about 37,500, which with the addition of the sugar beet harvester would bring the investment in machinery up to $28,795. This is nearer the suggested optimum investment. The increase in the labor input could hardly be justified in practice, neither could the reduction in fertilizer and crOp expense. At least another 3700 could be spent on fertilizer to bring applications more in line with suggested optimum rates. It is also likely that the other crop expenses of gas, oil and machinery repairs would be increased due to the additional machinery. Although caution must be taken in interpreting the results after calculating the high profit point, it is useful in that it gives the farm operator something to shoot for. It is also a guide as to the inputs which could be profitably increased or which need further examination. CHAPTER VI CONCLUSIONS AND APPLICATIONS IN THE UNITED KINGDOM Cbnclusions The cash crop farms of the Saginaw Valley and Thumb area of Michigan, represented by the sample in this study, appeared to be fairly well adjusted to the conditions existing in 1957. Im- provements are likely to be obtained by new technology, such as improved varieties of crops, particularly wheat; better techniques of weed control, particularly in relation to sugar beets and beans; and improved methods of planting and/or thinning sugar beets. Labor efficiency will probably be largely improved by attention to the re- turns to other inputs as the ideal of equation (2), Chapter II, is approached. Some possibilities of reducing labor requirements have been noted but much improvement in this direction, except during the spring peaks, cannot be assumed. A linear programming study in this area may show that a recombination of crops, either before or after these technical ad- vances are made, could increase the returns to inputs. However, any improvement in this direction would be influenced by the strict allotments at present enforced for wheat and the acreage quota system for sugar beet growing. The build up of diseases in this area due to overcropping, particularly in relation to sugar beets and beans, will also dictate the pattern of crop combination in the not so distant future. 81 82 Higher yields might not automatically cause increases in the marginal productivities of the inputs. The demand for the main crops in this area is relatively inelastic so that price de- clines might result from increased production. Present conditions, therefore, would suggest attempting to improve the productivities of inputs within existing yields. Reduction in labor requirements per acre by increasing farm size and technological advances would appear to be another approach. This, of course, is in line with present economic thought and the trend to a larger business unit; but if this actually increases overall production, as the evidence of increasing returns to scale suggests, the farmer may be no bet- ter off. This observation is made with reservations because of the danger of extrapolating beyond the range of the data in this study. The lower return to machinery investment on the smaller farms, because of the relatively inflexible and expensive units of input required, also lends support to the trend to spreading this high investment over a larger acreage. Adequate drainage is essential in this area. The study shows high returns were obtained to this investment in 1957 and other evidence1 suggests that high returns are normally expected in average years. Further detailed investigation of returns to drainage investment over a longer period of time, may be worthwhile. 1c. R. Hoglund, 93. cit. 83 Applications in the United Kingdom One of the original intentions in this research project was to study the substitution of machinery for labor in this area. Unfortunately, because the farms in the sample were generally well adjusted, and this appears typical of the area, insufficient dif- ferences occurred to pursue a detailed investigation of this nature. This was a disappointment because of the usefulness of such information in the U. K. However, one of the few maladjusted farms was selected to illustrate the applications of functional analysis at the micro level, and at the same time this illustrated a rather obvious case of the substitution of machinery for labor. This, in turn, illustrated the potentiality of the functional type of analysis to assist in the examination of the substitution of machinery for labor on less well adjusted farms. These are probably the case in the U. K., particularly in relation to labor and machinery. The danger of high intercorrelations of the input cate- gories reducing the reliability of the estimates of the regression coefficients is demonstrated by this study. Dr. Glenn L. Johnson, who supervised this study and has had considerable experience with this type of study, had not previously met with such high inter- correlations. Thus it is hoped that such an extreme example rarely occurs. Purposive sampling is a method of attempting to reduce the intercorrelations of the input categories, if this can- not be undertaken, the sample size must be increased to compensate. 84 The University agricultural economists, in the U.,K., have the time and facilities to do this. In the field, where the local farm management advisers and District Officers of the National Agricul- tural Advisory Service2 are left to collect data from which farm business reports are compiled, time is an important factor. They are not usually in the position to undertake purposive sampling. However, the records are, or could be, made available to the Uni- versities. This would enable larger samples covering similar types of farms over a wide area to be compiled; the danger of in- troducing more variables would have to be watched. Grouping of the farms is done strictly on an enterprise and farm size basis, as op- posed to the Area Reports of the Michigan Co-operative Extension Service.3 Hence more reliable estimates of regression coefficients may be obtained than has previously been achieved by using these records.4 The recent institution of the "mail-in" system for collecting farm records by the Michigan Co-operative Extension Service could result in worthwhile estimates of marginal productiv- ities to be made. The farm records collected in the U. K. would have to be improved somewhat to ensure more precise measurement of 2The district Officer is almost the equivalent of the County Agent in the Co-operative Extension Service. 3F'arm business reports issued by the Michigan Co-operative Extension Service are to be made available on a stricter farming type basis for 1957 onwards. 4Louis S. Drake, "Problems and Results in the Use of Farm Account Records to Derive Cobb-Douglas Value Productivity Functions" (unpublished Ph. D. dissertation, Department of Agricultural Econ- omics, Michigan State College, 1952). 85 the input categories. The major difficulty would be streamlining the accounting procedure to make the newer measures of efficiency worthwhile, the objective use of which has been demonstrated in this study. It would also entail an extensive education program for the officers concerned regarding the theory behind, and the need for, such improvements to measures of farm business effi- ciency. Many found difficulty in grasping the principles of farm management analysis; currently employed and older members of the profession even ridiculed that approach as being unnecessary; hence, any further advances may have a difficult passage. A bias may result from the use of these farm records in that they are frequently assumed to be obtained from the better managed farms. Strictly speaking this would mean that any conclusions can only be applied to this group of farms. The same would therefore apply to conclusions reached by traditional methods from these farms. However conclusions would probably also apply to the so- called not-so-well managed farms, as the tendency is for them to be more poorly adjusted. It is the author's Opinion that in the U. K. this difficulty would not tend to apply as the records ob- tained were fairly representative of managerial ability. The problem of studying multiple enterprise farms has not yet been fully resolved;5 as mixed farming is more general in the U. K. than the U. 8. this problem is emphasized. 5ChristOph Beringer, 22. cit. 86 This method of analysis should complement other methods of farm management work. They are not substitutes. A new slant on the farm business is obtained which gives a better basis for estimating efficiency. This is particularly helpful in relation to labor utilization and machinery investment. When making up standards of efficiency of farming assuming fixed acreage, most of the other inputs such as feed, fertilizer or livestock have measures of efficiency derived from independent input-output studies and more confidence can be placed in them. This is not so with the inputs of labor and machinery investment; these have little or no independent evidence from which measures of efficiency can be made. Supplementary studies to determine the marginal value productivity of labor for different crops and livestock would be useful in planning the best combination of enterprises where labor is the limiting factor. This is particularly so in the U. S., and the same position is rapidly approaching in the U. K. Interpretation of the results for individual farms depends on how good a job is made of selecting homogeneous farms for the sample and the efficiency of measuring the input categories. Per- haps more important is the assumption inherent in the Cobb-Douglas production function of constant elasticity, although modifications can be introduced into the function to overcome this difficulty.6 6A. N. Halter, a. 0. Carter and J. G. Hocking, "A Note on the Transcendental Production FUnction," Journal of Farm Economics. Vol. XXXIV, NOVs 1957' ppe 966‘974e 87 The method can also be applied to the study of resources at a macro level, to aid in the better all around allocation of these resources. Fbr instance, the immigration of labor off the farms in the U. K. is continuing; increasing machinery investment and farm size may be Spart of the answer. Also pertinent is the recent Farm Improvements Hill which provides assistance in the modernization of buildings and other fixed investments to land. Many farmers, while welcoming the assistance, question whether this may be the best allocation of capital on their farms. Knowledge of the marginal value produc- tivities of inputs would help give a more objective basis for con- sideration of these problems. APPENDIX A Estimated Marginal Value Productivities for Some of the Farms in the Sample 89 Omaha Gamma awnan anaON waned Hnmnn oEoosH macaw Hosao< oommv. nvub aenae. naam canne. aaeo Amman. mamas amuse. moan comma. beam Anasmaomv ensoaxm homo a hosuuuoaek ammun. wanna mecca. comma mama». gamma mam». Omaha mama. amend anon. comma Auasuuouv .ame>sH emosqssa human. mvaH nnmen. mesoH mama. omega wvnam. muamm anwom. comma gamma. nemmn Anhsunomv .vno>sn massages: marina» Goad gamma Gamma «human Co.,»... camau NN madam mama N560..." my Assumes: hone..— Aueaus unasanflav Nm.on on.wn HH.en am.ao ma.e¢ ao.nm panache 5H.a~ aom mu.an «am mm.mn mum na.nn oea wa.mm awn ow.nm «ma vacuumed: «omen ea each m sash N such on Bush ON lash Ha Essa Gamma beawu aabmn wwoa manan naomu eloosn macaw «s5904 awmnm. some sauna. "can Name. mean mean. mama meme. Oman Once. when Anasuaomv emseaxm menu a aosuuwuseh Hmmam. unanm abom. Gamma Aman. NNHOH Amen. woman mean. mama anmm. momma AessHHocv .umo>:H owsswema amum. anOH «moan. onm onnm. among amen. bums ”mun. ammo muen. aama Anasauomv .ame>sH massages: am.aon mu an.abu NH om.nmm mm.au an.onm ne.o~ nn.anm mm.n~ an.vbN an Amsvcolv honed Amused omasufiuuv mm.ae om.ae o~.om mo.nm n~.na oo.am mosadsm an.wm wnn av.nm was om.vn ma a~.aN as ¢~.am on mm.mm ma macaques: ”used Edam .assso Edem— Jsea Edam .9655 Edna .953 Edda .vssa Edam .0935 n sacs ¢ 11a E...— S suns 3 Ea..— s 5.3— e ...—as H admxHBDDnomm HDAQ> Az .vwfi .audso ab: .amm .«flmsc «Nana manm manna. vnnofi Caddb. Hanna ownom. wmwon momma. nbflnn henna. Oman Nhaun. OH¢On www.mnm oo.wn ma0.0aN 00.nm Hn.nv Na.nN ohm No.an OO.~N NNm m>2 .«mfl .usdsc m>2 .amm .vsmno anaam eacosu amend Hesao< Aegeanemv eeseaxu menu a touaaaaaos dmeh. Dmvb Hanna. Amman Anasduomv .ume>sH vacuums: anabn. manna Auasnnomv .one>:H mandamus: Assasoflv honed Aeesos euasnnuav message messages: "used one.abu OO.HD mv.w¢ oo.Hn oo.mm can m>2 .vmm .vudsd an Shah mm Inch an Shah n Shah on flash cognaucou .. x mam - C - '..- In ‘ mun-.1 v- .. .‘l‘ 'v. ... 9... . . .C .o.. ~nI -—e...¢..a‘ I ‘u,... ACQ‘D- ...u. . ...-» o.,-I~- v-h- -.q "n * -~ eun- 0- to... o . . . ' w . n .\ '- _. .1. -‘ . -. ..n .- ~lf¢~e.‘-- --- unr- . .m- .. . ‘ . . . -. . I . ._ I | . qv.-- -.- ‘. .a .... Is I .- . a a . < .0. se«a.—‘.A-c.‘-e.-~-. “we. ......c I I.’A s'. 0-1... ‘ . u . v v .- ~- --«.-.-.--.-—...'..--.. -v ,,. __‘ , _. ’ l' ' e~'_' ' I gene - no I'»-OV"e ...-va- .1. . ~. . .. . °—~"-~-~- he“. . u ‘ -ae-. ...-...- , o. o .7... ,. ..... _ _‘ . ,. . ‘.. .o- -.-.-.‘~ .... - ...- .. .. . -.-. . .‘.._‘ .. - - ..........- ,. ...“..- e- ”I-hg. unfit. oe-o .- -m-'- ¢~ .. - ‘R.-..~s.‘ . t I ' n ‘ ‘ ‘ . ‘1.~.~ ee'Ooo . .. --. >~..- .e ....l. e.‘ Imm-su-v-flfiv'e . e“ . \ a an . . . o . .... g- . .... ... ...:,". on ..e .... a v- .u- a. v - .... s 0a.. ends. a e ean' ‘ ~ Io sm‘u , ‘hA .- . a e. . -. ...; a. . a, 7. ......p #6 m n. n. ... .... . . .e 4. ga.- ...-...“ .... s. e ‘ ‘4‘ .' . *'.- ~I4~ he. »- . ”‘2' AA -e ..~ ' .-ems - .. g a,-. p-.-... 9‘. . ’ . 0 ‘ ' r ' V l ”"4 - ~ I .---m~e- -.'-‘ n ur. s-»~. .7 _ . . . . - ‘u u u s ..,..I Isa-a 4e. -..s.eus- ‘ ‘U-"‘~‘Q‘MI‘.. .. ‘ .- . i o -. -.s -‘ n V an. ~,.m-\m-: .- n . . ‘» n m . . . ... s... g m l- . -.--. «. n,» v.-Aau---. 'I .'--§. 'le ... --.--n . m-’ . . l .g .- . - . ... v. . . . .... .,..~. v\.. n «yo-see I: 'w . e m ...- -.- '- ‘ .... e. . -m-:'k0 I-" no em.- 9 , . no.4 s- m~\. .II. ' V l . . . \ .. v . . ~-- 0 , .a- e~ v .o -- -- . " . w . . " ‘ .' . - ~- ~ . .. ... . . . . 'e V ' 1 v . _ . t I .e ‘1‘. ...s- . . v' a. .. .. ... - - A .s o. ... . ..e l e-. ...-s, as. on on I‘I I‘ I.-.D-~ m. ‘ . I e . . ' ‘ . - -.-- n- . . ‘ . - .. el‘ ,..., - 9 . .- .. e .... m -.. ..-.-.. - ~ . - . ‘- ~‘ 4- ‘ev V. n . «... . a. u. s u 5 - In. ' a. 4 .. e m - m ..r .-..' a e n-mt- ‘*-.‘l' a ‘.- ~‘U v-0’ " ~ "‘-"-"".""‘ “ "s.‘- . .. rev. .u.. 1' V. e '. I -. .. tn... I, - ~'- ~ - —.:A nee-... . u I o. a .9. <‘ - .- .. . a ll.‘ ---m...--e _ . .. f ll~- peo- . . . , . ‘- ‘ t . t 1 c -“ . n . . e u I l - l u . , ‘ a ' I re .-. .~— a. ..-. ~.: , u. .- _ I ‘I I . e. I I _. | \- ‘~ no, , . .. 7 - 94 Gross Income - 1 2 3 h 5 Physical Ending Total Beginning Annual Crop Income Production es Valuation 1+2 Valuation Prodifition 3.. Wheat : Cash crop bu. Seed bu. Oats: Cash crop bu. seed bu. Barley: bu. Corn: Cash crop bu. '1 Beans : Cash crop bu. Seed bu. Sugar Beet Tons Other Custom work a machine rented Produce consumed in house (not livestock) Other income from crop source _ Gross income, excluding livestock 3 1 2 3 h 3 5 7 Sales Ending Total Beginning Purchase Total Annual , Valuation 1+2 Valuation n+5 Prod. Livestock income Milk 8: other dairy produce Cattle Poultry & eggs Sheep 8: wool Other livestock income fi. Gross livestock income $ Grand total 33 o . ‘4 ' u an... ’ O ..- o .. - .- .. .- u .. t I '1 .... .... .. .. ,I .. . ,., I l‘ u g V O f‘ a o .l.‘ 50’ I I n u . It. I o . I u. I .‘o ~ .r' u .. no t o \i n I -_-§ r ( I P I I t' ' C o v 4‘- I r. 7.. l f . I O .. , ~~ -. s“ I I 3 1" I I'- ‘1‘: ‘ ~r- r! ~OQI ' .‘l-h . rho .- . D\” unto uvu. ‘ I .- . . , , . 'o'. v ‘a ' u.“ v - “... ID. ..I . ~ \. w I o u e A ~ -. - -y . - . u . . . - ‘ ... ... .. . -§ sv . .l ‘. I‘ ' . . . 1 ¢ . o . .. . . . _. . . ».v c. '_..‘., . ...-n to | . . .. . o . .. -o a U '..o : ~ - --‘ r u , 4 ... «.5- ,.r ...... 0 ~' . - c-v -.‘— .-- ~ u“ -- .. ,. . .- i . u Onh- ‘I ... u I o . A r . ... . u '- w 6'. o . “ ’ ‘,,. Id : ... s I . . c J c I o l\'- - u . n \ -v . a a. ‘ .... ' ‘ . - Io.‘ a. A. n ‘ ~ ‘ p u .. ... 95 ..u. Fertilizer & Time Analysis ”86 Quantity Price. Cost ' Lin; Total 5.» Less that used for livestock crops (ES Net cost to cash crop production g.) Residual Fertilizers & Lime: (cropland only) Only if very different in beginning and ending inventory. Difference in fertilizer and lime usage between 1957 8: 1956 or the new. ' P205 lbs. difference 3: $5 a x 95 - g,» K20 lbs. difference 3: 53’ = x ¢ =- a) N2 lbs. difference 3: % - 3: ¢ - $ Difference in Residual Value $9 Substract if difference balance is carried forward to 1958, or add if brought forward from 1956 and before. Total Fertilizer G: lime investment 9 Alterations in cropping during last 1; zear : .uu u-q o--~- I‘d—A V. 1»- ...‘¢ ~ - in 4...... a,_..-- u»- “- III...“ .-~ in, .. . - .- t~ - - .. ... _-~ - D Or . .- I .... o I n u . . - ..u . a .- . . , -s ’1 - ‘ 0 o . . . o . ’ I . . . - . - i . U ' . ' , o - V 'x w a . ' O I ". . 1 . .. ~ - . . I . . - »- n .- d In ...-Q‘.q-' '2‘ .n - g-U ' 'n- -.-. .- . '-o v .- Or .. l - -- A -...» ' a \ . . . - .. .. . - .I ‘ I . | u o l v n l ‘ . ’ ' u .- .. -' u. I ‘ . l .i . 1. I - .; . 5 - n . .- . V-I \. A-“ " l ' . .i u o a 1 . 7 d . .- l ...-p - . ..u : O ,4 . . . .- . . ..... Q I .- -. ~'i ...... . .. .. .. l -- I I J.. . . n' . o . n n, . . o ~ A n I ' . .- c -' n u .: .\ . Il . ‘ '. ' .g I - l: A ,l ' ~ I; . . ‘ r .. ... A I. . ... v”. un~~ 0 .- a u a 96 Other expenses inning ture Total Ending Annua aluation aluation Cost‘ A. Power 8: machinery: Custom work an machinery hire Fuel & oil for farm use (less refund) Implement 8: machinery repairs (not of an investment nature) Haulage ' Electricity (farm share) Auto operation (farm share) Other Total power & machinery costs B. Fertilizer & lime investment (p. h) 0. Seed D. Other: Baleing wire 8: sacks Crop sprays & pest control Postage, telephone, etc. Miscellaneous Total other costs Subtract or add value of difference in winter wheat, clover & alfalfa stands. (1). 6) E. Livestock: Feed purchases: concentrates others Veterinary't medicine Breeding fecs Other, dairy sundries etc. crop expense V otal livestock expenses t Total of other expenses (crop & livestock) §9____ Ehcpenses not to include maintenance & repair work of an investment nature to buildings ,mnachinery and land, or depreciation, interest 8: insurance charges. "w” a ' O cg. ~- .. .. ' o . -. . .o . I . ' 'n a, 4.‘ 'v 1 . . "-'~ . h l . ..- ' on, l‘n .~~. . . _ I , ... - .. _ . a”... , .~ on... .. . . . ~ . o cl l.- \. '- . n. \ .' ‘a 1' I " . I' ' . . )\ ~ I - A i K ‘ . ‘ 97 -6- .Establishment and Valuation Winter Wheat, Clover’& Alfalfa Stands Only if there is a difference between beginning &.ending inventory'acreages (1957). Costs &.va1nes at 1957 Prices. 1956 fer 1957 for 1957 crop 1958 crop 'Winter Wheat Fertilizer costs per acre (excluding N2 top dressing) Seed cost per acre Other costs Tota1.per acre costs Multiplied by acreage Total cost of establishment of winter wheat Difference in cost or valuation t Clover &.alfa1fa seedings Brought forward from 1956 Seeding Acreage Age Condition ' Value value . per acre ” ” —r Total value t ' Carried forward to 1958 Total value h Difference in valuation 8 NB Add.valuations to crop expenses (p.5) if difference balance is brought forward from 1956, or subtract if carried forward to 1958. - - u~.“.. . C i I. u . I ‘-.~,. ' I c .. I o . n - 0 a. . . ~ m .- Q n - o ~~ouua a z - . . . -.. ..- -~.. u ' n C IV I v . n - -\ . ‘- . t . u I . I: ,0 O I _ ' h' . a " - .- ,.,.. ... ’u‘ ~ >0 u . I . a a . l . I , v . u ’ tr . . c . . on v... . n» I u . - ,.‘ --av-vo- _ .~ a c . ...... r n u, . o . . - o . . ‘ -~ - c - I .. . u ‘ .v . a . o I u . v n . ...~ 0 y 0 V . ,. . . n I. - , . Jh . a ., . . .. n ‘.-4.,.a¢ in...» u ‘y- v, - u - ’o . . _ . . . . . < a n X ' _ n ‘ , .... o . . . i . .. . l t. -_ ‘ g ._ . n... ' I . . u. . .- . ' | . 9 A ' "Wutl 'u‘... I'I‘QI.,- - '. .. . \ r . a w' . .. . .0 . , .' f' !- . I 1. ... .o .u --.‘.o ... . -uo- m-.|I‘l .- ...-t... .... . a ....- a...-n..— oh-o -- - .p—u .- .‘~Lr. . ..— . l w v .a --.«..- .‘n—usu .‘ - .’. . - . ...... l l -- "I— ~a- '. l, in! '0' - 1“. " . u -- g- .e. ..c vi .. ~fiv~-oc..-u .... . . .. . ; v 1. u . ~ I - -.- -.a..--\. -....._,._~...._.... -.~-... .. . . ... v . o .. ... -.. - . ..- — l . an... n». ..-.- . p-..¢un..a—---.‘- ... . - ...:-«.—- s: -4 U. '1 g ' ‘ , . , .. . . . . ..r . I ‘ y . ‘ a |~.'.I . ..- ..- Q ~- r‘ .u . QQMIU - .4 ' ~- .' w‘ .. --.. . .- . . . _I ,. -I ‘ n. . “.oa~A..«- . '\ C "v‘ ...-. .a r . . ‘1. ...-co 0‘ a 'I l' -. . A. . ... I ~ - o .0 . o A c 98 Machinery'& Eguigment Investment Item Combine Bean harvester Corn picker Sugar beet—barvester Beet loader or corn p 3 Corn 8..- arain handling: Marato'r , Blower or Auger Drier Cleaning equipment er or ‘ lime oer Seeder equi ons & trailers Newer Cultivation equipment: bottom Spring tooth harrows or sp Clod buster Cul Field cultivator Roller Cultivator: row Rotary'hoe Down the row thinner Leveller Grader or Bulldozer .~ r.... u. . . . u t ‘ _ I c ...- e. .u I..'.l. at.- o .. no. ‘ . . a . . ~ - o I' I ~ . -~«.-.- . ~ «It. r‘v 0‘ - u r 4 '- ' - . . .... a . g . :1 o '. - . g .. .. o '« - -- - .. --v . t»-. u to --o e.- ...~ . ~ - - - o - - v. 1 ... . . . a.-. IQ. - 0-. o . it“- u I a -- ... . .5. .o o c , ._ - -. ; . . ... -.. . -.., 0 b- ur-- . u - .- ..I-. .I u - n >- ‘- ‘ - .0 v v . ...‘. .... ~, _ . .. . ... . a . n I o .- u v .. . O. .- - .... - .p en... . Al-o.- ,u— - - .o ~ .- —. .. . a - ."*~‘ on - » - n u . - . I n. .i . . . 1 ‘ c - . .v a u. . A . J ‘ . . o a ,,, .. c -. .- p...-.¢. - ' . .... . .. o ...- D , .I“ . I. a u . ... . r c a . a pa. ,- a}. v u o o u-t 4 u .- - a. . . . . ,. '. - ...A.‘ » . n u o .~~ . ‘ . a. o I ’ D. . - I -.§u I ' n ., . m n , n a t . 0."... .4. 0 ~ I a n.3’. :l-u-u ,» ... . 0 ~ .-'~ up- —~ . n . .1. ., .. ., . o.-‘ . . ... . . o . . . no. . , ’\ ~> _ _. ..- . ‘ o- .- . ‘ ..' I O ~l . » 1 U . -4. 'Ir l - a . ‘. ' ‘r .- ~.. I ....\-.. . .«r . - ... . ... u ...i - . . n . -. 0 s . 9 u..- .... .-. u-auuoo- ... - o o- ~o u- s I . l . ' . h.... u ‘ .. . I u D ‘Iv . I. u- 5' --s- I.‘ n .. . . .. ..., - . ~ 1 . o . . . . J. a .. -.. a I o l .1 O ... ‘D 5.. I. u 0'01. ~ 99 Item No. Age Condition value Other crop machinery Wbrkshop egpipnent: welder Engines, motors "WECEP pump General farm.tools L I (forks, shovels etc.) ! +~ Total crop machinery investment t Add preportion of investment for farm automobile $ Livestock equipment Mbwer 7 i Rake ‘ ._ Forage harvester __. Blower Feed grinder Manure spreader Manure loader ' ' ‘__ Dairy equipment . Other livestock equipment 1 _L__ Total livestock machinery investment B Beginning inventory, total machinery investment B Book value of machinery investment :3. values Sales Use be &.valuation at 1-1- Purchases I *Note: 01331 a dad. alue Date tem Date Item tal Prop. Beginning inventory: Prop 0 added Prop. subtracted Total Machinery investment 9 Netes on.machinegy (ownership shareing?) b ., 6 .1. .~ I . .. ‘-‘l . I. v‘ -'o. - I. n,, . a .5.» . , s -u-.. u. - 0- 4- - o‘c- II 3. - . . ~\ .~ u ... . . . . n , . . onions-uuv- ‘ .' v-J.I'--.-_. m,- . . I ' I \ t ‘ n t f . ‘o .... > - . a I v. 0 vs- A.>. I. - :-... _ . . .. , c." .... .7 ...... . .... .., ‘ .... .. . . , n .... , .I... . - . . . . r9. a. . ..- i H u-Lo .0 -‘ I.. ~.. I I. . ->. . I I n . ... u. a- , . ‘ .' '~'.' I... -. , . O .... . I .. l '. . . ‘ ~.. (I. . ..uy.. .‘ . . . l I . . . . v i . . I .... .- . . . .. . . o ‘l ‘ .-. . . I. I, I an t. I ,, . . . ,.‘_ . .. . . u .. . .. . .. I | . . , ...>'..:_ . i ‘. . . o\. -l I l .. . . ,- OII-o -‘I .5 -... ...... .‘._. ..“l- .1 COO O --- -I§o-. ..-‘on n.- - .- I . s ‘; . .1 - . I I - P . . I U .. ‘I‘, ,. '1' . 'v I...“ -O O. - ~.\~o~o~-u--. r.‘ I - .- A I . ‘ u A l o . . v. a o. »-.< .. \ _ . . I ~'| r ' . . . . L I p . . 0 .¢ , ... .. . .i . .. ‘ ' I I , I . . c. i : I . l > ' . . o ‘\ u' 0 I '.‘l-o.~.~ofi I-‘ ,-~ ..- -.- ...- . -o. 1. ,. _ .. .... .V§A.o...-- . 7 ' . . y- - -. . Q I. . I . » . 0‘ I a a .00 '1. v ‘ .U‘..u. ._~ ~ . .. I "av -u~ . V n‘n'lI-h 'Q'“II‘-." I o .I -~ - .0... - « 4'.-I ‘ . c 1 ~‘o . - . .. . . . a... ~_. . 4| 1 ' . . .. . - u . qt: o.‘ - \ . . . --"I-.-‘ ....... . . ., . . Id. V‘ n- ‘ .A .. I .-., . . .. n. ‘v A.. I p— I o- I . ~ I ‘ .I'- l I v I... ‘ on — . . . .. -9- 100 Buildin s 570% to include that used for livestock & fodder or not used. " ' Size farmers estimate of invesunent value Liachinery storage 8: workshop Sq. ft. Crap storage: a. Small grains or beans bu. be com crib b“. Total Livestock buildings & fodder, forage etc.: Farmers estimate of total building investment: Drainage (cropland only) Undrained not requiring drainage requiring drainage Drained ‘ good fair, imperfect but cropable ‘ very poor TOTAL crop acreage Tiles (discount old 2" tile systems) (‘I R? acres acres acres BOPBO acres acres Size Type Depth Length of run in rods Replacement Investment 1," cost per rod Total tile inveth $ . . ... ... ' ‘- I . . .i o ._ .. . t. s ‘ I I .- , ' 9 P - " I I O. I 5' I ‘ | I ' ' I ’ ' ‘ ‘ . U I 1‘ I t I ‘. . - u. .0 . . . sq. - . .- . . , . V I r ~ ‘ '- l ~ l-KI 1 .. .. _ . _, ‘. _‘ I '_ l V w . "I.-o “..,... ‘.. .. .. .4“. ...-Ia ...,o- .p-.- I~l~ I-4.*l-o-.I-‘-I'I>.'II--"- II~-.-. Into-4 I. . , ‘ oo ‘ ' ' I I I ‘ . I I . I ' I ~ -' . -- ..I — . . ‘ .. - I p, . v - .I ‘ "”“' ""‘"""‘“"-‘ ‘ " ' ' "-0"" --I '! -7 - u »I-- o-r- II ~..e.-._.,. ......ox. :v_-..- v sun-our \QI~..-.- .... w.¢-. -o-m -. i. . ..Q. ..- .-- ... . .avn .. . .7. .._-_., l ‘ ' . y c . .. ‘:,2 H. . .‘ ‘L.....'.. '_ I.'._, I , “ ‘ 1 ' . ’ ‘ 0 ‘~ ~ ‘ .e'. .I . l ' 1.. . .. . .1 .- ‘ . .... “ ‘I'.. - 'l' ' ' ' ' ” ' ’ I I h- I. - ~vl . ‘ ‘ ~ - n - ..-.Ili “I - ~ i , b ' ‘ d\-‘ J " ’( ‘0 I ‘ . u. I"- . I l . {e . ' I " -'Q ' I“ .' ' ' ‘ "’ -‘ ‘I 1' I ..r . e ' . ‘ ' ‘ I ... It I . ,o- , .. o"‘-..¢—- > I ---.- .. . - - - . >- r. .._ . I ' '_ . ‘9! fl. ‘ . on: ._ . . . o o- n o. -‘ ..- _ -.- - — _ n . ... I . ., . ,. ... . - . no: .. I. IneI- hr .- I u-JIO‘I’ .o‘ -. ....I.'.'OI I... u . .., .4 .... .- , . .. ...o-....-...,—... . . V...‘. ...I. .7... .- ‘ i-......—.........~ - -......~ -..o- - I . . O b ' . I I I I’ ‘ I": II , 'h l‘.'. ‘J . ' " I ‘ ' - .. ' . ‘ I ». ,. - . I v . I _ \ ~ I - \ .. . . e . - o v I I V I ' - . ; . . _ I.- I . . _ . ,. . ’. .. ' . II I L. e ‘7 '} ' 1‘! '\ :-. . I - _ - ‘ o I I , l .g' I ‘ ' ‘ u , I ‘- I-o oir‘“ I... -I.- .,n ...- I '. ' . ' ' “- . il. I.. . , . . ... \ ' ! ~ .h _. . ‘ x -. I» . . . ... I . I — - l \ -.' .‘-' '.’ ‘ e " -~ - o ._ ’ " ' 'I Q I . I F ' . . 1' , w 1, -A "'O-o. -'.-- C I i I . I I In. -_ . ..I g '7 '. V. I - v . .‘-. | ‘ . - ---- ---r..a\.o ' . V by III ..'JI .v. . . - :\u. I- . . . . '..~¢|- ,. ' I I‘ O ' .‘ ‘ .. '0 ‘9‘ .. I. ‘I.‘ . ..-,-\,v; '_ ' I. ' ." \ ‘ l 1' f . ' . I . ' .... .... ... ,....v\. ‘ ., .' o I. 'l , or- I . '. . . . . - I I A. n P I '. ... \IIIIU' ” - ' ' .I - . l . ‘ 1'; . A ‘ . ‘ . .‘ ( V -‘... A... . . .. I , .4 . $1 — . . -.. . . .,. . - , -‘ I I ; I .. x. , . . , i - I . -I- x r . .. . --- ....I -...o-4...-.. ..- I. -. .- e ,. .. , . ... __‘ . . _.~. ...-'_“J,‘. . . -____‘_._~r- '_ _- _.--._. ..‘ . _..__‘ “’_ .h .‘ ‘ Q. ‘ . l d C l p l I ‘ 1 . . 4 ~, I ~ .. . ‘ ‘ V >‘ ,. - 0’ I . ‘ ‘ I ' . ' I ‘I‘ _ ' . _ J ‘ . . ‘ . . . .4 I u’ . ‘ I \ I . ‘ ‘ f. ,- . I l I . O y ‘ ... we.....:-r. .q-III. ......w: .a ca I . ,. - , -. I >.. . .. , . I _ .1. »-- ~.. I, .4. 1...... . . -. -an—a.r..o.- onuo -v . ...-aunt. .,...,.~- I. - -~ " '4“ ‘ V ‘ I"' ‘ " 1 . I I ‘ ’ I I I v. Q - . -' ¢ ‘ . . '3 ' I ~ ‘ " - I I ‘ A .a . 4~ . ‘ Ao- ..---o . .. ~ 1 a. - ‘. . ‘ l . ’ ,. D I - I . ‘-‘ I--_ -- A .v~.. I C .- . . . . l 'l ' ‘I ~ - I . u .- .. .—. I .A ... .. ., . .o I . . ~ .. O ‘ I ‘ . . . . . - . . . . . . . . .o . . u ' I .. - .. ~ . _"l.l .. . . . I. - . . . _-'\ ‘ l ' t I .l ‘ ' I c - , .- . . .... .. q, , . .A ‘, .. , - g C I - - ‘ . . I , ,- . I i . .- . . ..,. D.‘ x - I~ .. .I . \. . ~ -. .- ‘ t . l. , I I ' " " v . - I I, ‘. .-la . I .a. . O ’ ...-.— . on - .I I .- .. . -‘ ‘ 5 . ' ' ‘ I I ' I 0-. Cd < ' ‘ ' I' ‘ I. '1 I- I 10‘ l ..' .i O ’ - ' ’ ‘ C .‘ — I I 1 ‘ ‘ . .... ....-....A.-,.4._.-.-..,... .. - -, . ’ V ‘ t - .-.,.. .‘e .. . 9.. ... -..-../...-... .—. .7 u . _. ... . -. . . ‘ . ..." mo. .: . o u .‘ 4. .... -W. ......In 'I' w-.: . ., .- V . . . ...). -..» .. _ - I ' ‘ a -‘ 1 l ., l~h 1.. - .- .I g - v 'I - n . . .. . .. , ‘I. ..,...,. _. .. -. 2 I. , - . . ., .... ‘ ... . . : I ; J 9 I,’ I ' v. .- . . . r . . _ .... ., .( ...‘ _ ...,i, a - .- . . u . 4. ‘..,. :V r I ' ' I ‘ I .. d I - V ’ . . l r ‘0‘. ~-. ».. I.A.p.u‘ a. V- . ... . ‘ . o~ . y. 1.... - .I qe-Q‘.-~ ...,I..I -.‘4‘. .-. .-.'.,'p.,. ....“Qp . 'I. ~. -'.‘~ ...-... .-.I. II x 0-. ”.5- I .I I . ' i 2 . . .. 101 -10- Ditching (farm investment only) Depth Length of run in rods Unit' cost Investment Total ditch.1nvestment 8 Other drainage investment Items Land leveling Culverts Settling tanks PUmps Other Investment charge for farm use of county ditches $ Total drainage investment $ Notes on drainage: I .-4~~ -.-‘|§» . ....A..A...,. .,. .- . »a----...A-. ~. woos-A .a v. . ~o 0‘ .| A ~ -. h - -.. -. --...~ . -- A-. - A - . - . . ...» ~. .~ .-‘.-. » A . . . ..-A I- . x u I . , _ a .. c . .l g ‘- - r . ' I u ‘ n-. 1‘ u ‘ ...l .V . .' . .. . .r. . I n . v I . t, x l _ Q I ' u n I l - . . A a - ‘ A A . n ' r. «- . . I ‘ . .4... ...an- ”.....-AA ..-u‘-A-.r-...-- n .. -.- r..n. .... ..u-n - he .m..-. -.. .... ....A... -- -. A s. . - nu...—-. -- ‘ A.-. ~ --"<-4 -~ '- . . A- .-. ~..-. - 7.. . .. . . . - A . . ... . .A - r.» \_.. .. u ~. .-. - .. . L ~ - .- 0- ‘ ‘ ' 1 , -. . A , ,7 .A. -7 . . .A .. ‘r .. ~ . . . A.A ... . ‘ A . . o . ‘ ’ I . . .l..» - u- . _ . -. . ~ . I. - . ‘ ,. . . , A .A. - - I . , . o .... . .- . . - [ . A pg. - 70. _ . . . . ., n _ --.P u A. - . A - .. - «HA , - . o -v . » .,, o .. a . s ‘ A .. A . , A. , v - . . . . . ..... g A .., . q .... A, . .. . - ,g. ... A __ ~ I o | -‘ v - ‘7 - . . u M o.-.-.- ... rhr. ... -. AA; ... A . A». . - . .- .. .— --. a .1 on» -- - m a .7 . ~ A , - .. -‘ o - \ ~ I‘ ' . . . .v - ‘ '1' ‘I' . '.- ‘ ‘ -.-\-I u. o - . 1 . . 1 f . " ' n -. ‘( ‘.‘ I Av ' ' ‘ , n -‘ --AII.0 ~--A.u‘.-c.... , .o - A 7 A .....-. u. -.. . . A. -u- 1.. n ., .., ....o.... ..A o .... n -.- n .A -. A . -- o ... _ .7 . ”or . _~ VA . w: -~ .A. '0' -- t 7% ~ . n — y w ..F 0 a . . ‘ . , n. . v v I--'- - - -—- .- ' :- a- .‘O -. - ... do n --.-A. \ A .q— , .- - - . \.u a. A- . A . - ..~-—-.- - n-n cl.‘ 1 . -.-A.-.. .. . n. v . . ‘ o . r . _ . . ‘ A 4 . . - - . A, . A --_ a g . u. . . _ \ . . ,.., ...-. ...., . g r . , A.. ,‘-~ . ... . . .. . .A .. . . . . A 7A.. , .n. A... , . , l . ‘ P a 1 .- .-- . . .u _ ' h. . . -. . . , , ., A o A . l . . . - - . ‘ ‘ A- - ~ ' I . l ' 0.. - A- -. A.. ..A . . -. .. .A-A , . , . .. .. An . .. ' . A I w A. -- ... ,_. .. , , A , . . . A . - ... . .‘ -... u.- 7’0. w \ ... . .. . .. A , .- - A . . AA . . . . . - ... r. . A- o .. - .- 7A - —. - ‘ o \ . . . A-.-.-. ... ..,A‘ ....07 A. .. . . .v. o~. A < - o . . . .. . A AAA-.§.., ,u . - - up. ~. ,._.,,_ -.- «‘.A A. .... .... g V...” . .. . o - ‘. . .. ‘ ‘ .7 , f y A I A- . . .1 A . ’ . '5' . . ,. '. A. . ,u. A u . A g.A-. ' u A . , . A , ' . A- ~ . . , I.”---- ~ . ‘I A . ‘ ‘ . n A , _ .\ . A _ - - -cA~ ~A - - -..-. u — ~ . . , . “A A . . . . . .. A . . - ..4 . ' Av. .A‘ - » - ~ «A -~ A . . .. A . A .- ... A ...\.-‘ I. A . A . - . --A . A. . A. » .A . ...- A _ g , . . . A A A. A . ... . .7 -. -- .o:.~ ,.. -.- . ... ....A n «A L ~ .A . . A -.A.- - . A . > . A ,,,__ , . _ _‘ . . .. I. 4.... ..-. , .. ,. ....... . A A..- . -- A - . ‘ ‘a t - I v o , ,- .- . . . ... . g. , .-..A—A. - .... :5, . .., . «pa. .A ...I. - o g .- ‘ ...r.~oy .. 1 . .: v - . . .A-.' a A... . A ~. . . n . . a ..A‘ . . .A. 1¢.--.-. ......AA._,. "....-.rw -~ .. .A 4 . - AA . . - _ .. ,_, ~‘. u -~ A ...,-., . , . , A . , c . . - . . A.,.. _-.,... A ,_. . .... ...... ., ..A... , I- . u - ' ~ - -- M ..,. . A n - .-. .- v . . . .. . . .-.. . . 4 A . n ... - , a» -~'- .-- u- u -‘ - v~ ~- - A , --' n - - . ~ . .11- 1 0 2 Assessment of farm.practices used and laborA&.machinery'organization 1. Crogging: (e.;. green manuring) 2. Cultivations: (e.g. minimal tillage) mm h. Preharvesting (e.g. PestA& weed control) 5. Harvesting 6. Other crqp handling procedures If the operator could start afresh, what machinery'&.equipment mguld he have and how would this be combined? I ' g I g u .. ... ‘ o .qu«;¢Jv-wac ... -..a. ...- I‘ A v- or“... . v y - .- ‘ o l \ ...! u' s. ..-- . .- . A ‘. -... . ,. . ‘ , 1 .. t . ,. -. u .. '4 . .a a . . .7 . '~.. .1 ....- ..4. - .n m .-.r. . .. - I .. a- ... ‘ . . . . n I A | ‘. . . A v ' . ' . I ' I u .' A O c. ‘ . .0” - U— . ‘ - _ - A\ I _ 7 ~' ’ | -, C . . ,V' . I Q .‘. - I . '. 4 . .- .. ..- .. . - - .. w 3 . A ‘o . u ‘ . ' ’. O O 1.- I . . ' I ~ -,-1 I _~ 'A e ' ’ 'l T . ' ' - | ' om-~...n.~_—-A~.~ . . -,- g - . . ... .. .. o-\ I ' l' l:". 0" D Vl‘l r ‘.‘ 2'..'\ I e . BIBLIOGRAPHY A. Books Bradford, Lawrence A. and Johnson, Glenn L., Farm Mana ement Analysis (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 19535. Dixon and Massey, Introduction to Statistical Analysis (McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc., Second Edition, 1957). Eisenhart, C., Hastay, M. W. and Wallis, W. A., Technigues of Statistical Analysis (McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc., 1947, First Edition). Ezekiel, Mordecai, Methods of Correlation Analysis (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., Second Edition, 1949). Knight, Frank H., Risk, Uncertainty and Profit (Boston and New York: Houghton Mifflin Co., 1921). B. Articles and Periodicals Beringer, Christoph, "Problems in Finding a Method to Estimate Marginal Value Productivities for Input and Investment Categories on Multiple Enterprise Farms, " Resource Pro- ductivity, hturns to Scale and: Farm Size, Heady, Johnson md Hardin, Iowa State College Press, 1956. Brofenbrenner, Martin, "Production Functions: Cobb-Douglas, Inter- firm, Intrafirn," Econometrics, XII, No. 1, Jan., 1944. Carter, H. 0., "Modifications of the Cobb-Douglas Function to Destroy Constant Elasticity and Symmetry," Resource ProductivityI Returns to Scale_gnd Farm Size, Heady, Johnson and Hardin, Iowa State College Press, 1956. Cobb, Charles W. and Douglas, Paul H., "A Theory of Production," The American Economic Review, Supplement, XVIII, March, 1928. French, George W., "A Report on Tests of Mechanical weeding and Thinning Equipment in Michigan," Proceedings of the American Society of Sugar Beet Technologists, 1952. French, George W., "The Extent of Spring Mechanization in the Eastern Beet Area, 1951," Proceedings of the American Society of Sugar Beet Technologists, 1952. 103 104 Guttay, J. R., Cook, R. L. and Erickson, A. E., "The Effect of Green and Stable Manure on the Yield of Crops and on the Physical Condition of Tappan-Parkhill Loam Soil," Social Science Societyof America Proceedings, Vol. 20, No. 4, Oct. 1956. Halter, A. N., Carter, H. O. and Hocking, J. G., "A Note on the Transcendental Production Function," Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. XXXIV, Nov., 1957. Robertson, L. 5., Cook, R. L., Rood, P. J. and Turk, L. M., "Ten Years Results from the Ferden Rotation and Crop Sequence Experiments," Michigan Agricultural Experimental Station Journal, Article No. 1331. C. Bulletins and Reports Farming Today, Area 8 Report, 1958, Co-operative Extension Service, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State Univer- sity. Fertilizer Recommendations for Michigan Crops, Extension Bulletin 159 (Revised), Oct., 1957. Michigan State University Co- operative Extension Service. Hoglund, C. R., "Managerial Decisions in Organizing and Operating a Farm,"‘§g, Econ. No. 625, Department of Agricultural Economics and the Agricultural Experiment Station, Michigan State University, Sept. 1955. Michigan Labor Market, Vol. x11, No. 4 (April, 1957), and Vol. x111. No. 4 TAprii, 1958), published by Michigan Employment Security Commission, 7310 Wbodward, Detroit 2, Michigan. Officia1_Tractor and Farm Equipment Guidg, (January-June 1957). Compiled by the National Retail Farm Equipment Association, published by Farm Equipment Retailing Inc., 2340 Hampton, St. Louis 20, Missouri. Official Used Car Guide (January 1957), published monthly by the National Automobile Dealers Used Car Guide Co., 200 S. 7th St., St. Louis 2, Missouri. Turk, L. M. and weidemann, A. 6., Farm Manure, Extension Bulletin 300, Co-Operative Extension Service, Michigan State College (June 1945). Table 1, page 7, compiled from "Fertilizer and Crap Production," Van Slyke, Orange Judd Publishing Company. 105 Whiteside, E. P., Schneider, I. F. and Cook, R. L., Soils of Michigan. Special Bulletin 402, Soil Science Department, Agricultural Experiment Station, Michigan State University (January 1956). D. Mimeoggaphs Boyd, James 5., Current Costs of New Farm Buildingg (Professor, Department of Agricultural Engineering, Michigan State University). Paper presented at the Rural Appraisers Conference, Grand Rapids, Michigan, 12th Sept., 1957. Hoglund, C. R., and wright, K. T., Estimated Labor Requirements for Sugar Beet Pgoduction in Michigan, 9.9 ton Yield, Four Methods of Production. Michigan Circular Bulletin 215, June 1949. Mechanical Thinning of Sugar Beets, 1955. The Monitor Sugar Beet Co., Bay City, Michigan. Schultz, Arthur B., Building and Equipment Costs, Department of Agricultural Engineering, North Dakota Agricultural College. E. Unpublished Material Davis, J. F., Robertson, L. S. and Sundquist, W. B., "Fertilizer Input-Output Studies, 1957." Conducted co-operatively by the Departments of Soil Science and Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University. Drake, Louis 8., "Problems and Results in the Use of Farm Account Records to Derive Cobb-Douglas Value Productivity Functions," Ph. D. dissertation, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State College, 1952. wagley, R. V., "Marginal Productivities of Investments and Expendi- tures," Selected Ingham County Farms, 1952," M. S. disser- tation, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State College, 1953. \ f 3“ aid!" u C t “3 vi? 2.“ ‘L‘ ‘7 I ‘ in i! S -- M 03L 9?"? Uta-t. 3% e ‘9 l da‘p A I. Bu mi- "I7'1!@fifllfliiflfifl'ififlflfllifl'flfiflflflITS