A321 fii 5 5‘2... 13!? via. 1. EEWAWW . , d . zq.... . ., . ”Nam. f9. 2:. .LIBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Essays on Institutional Ownership presented by William C. Gerken has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the Ph.D. degree in Finance 21:45- 3 Major Professo Signature “-/’8 /3'oo? / I Date MSU is an Afiinmtive Action/Equal Opportunity Employer 4..-.-._t_._._.-...._t_._.V_...._.-._._.-.—....-.-.-.—.-._.—.-.-._._.-.-.-.-.—.-.—.-.-.-.-.—.-.-._.--.-r.--.-.-A PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 5/08 Kthroj/Aoc8PresIClRC/DateDue.Indd ESSAYS ON INSTITUTIONAL OWNERSHIP By William C. Gerken A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State Ui‘iiversit.__v in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Finance 2009 ABSTRACT ESSAYS ON INSTITUTIONAL OWNERSHIP By William C. Gerken The first chapter addresses the link l‘)etween the liquidity of a firm’s equity securities and the ability of large shareholders to influence control of a firm. Using a sample of US. outside blockholdings from 1994-2005, I examine whether liquidity influences the creation of block holdings. Using an instrumental variable approach, I find that liquidity increases the likelihood of block formation. Consistent with prior theory, blockholders of more liquid securities take smaller stakes that do not precommit them to monitor. I find evidence that. the threat. of exit from a. block can discipline managers and that this threat. is more effective when liquidity is higher. While liquidity increases exit from existing blocks, I find no evidence that. illiquidity forces blockholders to actively monitor. Blockholders7 returns are consistent with liquidity facilitating costly monitoring. and blockholder choose forms of monitoring that are more effective when liquidity is higher. In the second chapter. we empirically examine empltwee ownership of institutional investment. management firms. \Ve show that empltwee ownership is common, and the majority of firms in this industry are employee owned. The distribution of employt-‘e ownership is consistent. with an optimal contracting equilibrium. It is more prevalent when it is less costly, more efficient, and when alternative incentives are. less attrac- tive. The level of employee ownership does not predict. risk—adjusted returns, also consistent with an optimal contracting equilibrium. Finally. we show that employee ownership predicts risk taking. Portfolios managed by employee owners have signifi- cantly higher tracking errors. betas. and standard deviations even after controlling for firm characteristics. In the third chapter, we use mandatory disclosures by investment advisers to pre- dict which firms have future incidences of fraud and other investment-related crime. We find that internal polices that allow for more potential conflicts of interest are associated with an increased level of future events. Internal monitoring and incentive aligning mechanisms lead to lower levels of future events. The presence of sophis- ticated clients is negatively related to the frequency of future events. Even after accounting for all the above factors, a history of disciplinary actions against the firm predicts future events. Overall, the required disclosure is useful for predicting events, and the probability of events is positively correlated with permissive firm policies and negatively correlated with internal and external monitoring. DEDICATION To my family. without whom this "(could not have been possible. iv ACKNOWLEDGMENT I am deeply indebted to my dissertation committee members: J tin-Koo Kang (chair), Steve Dimmock, Naveen Khanna, and Zoran Ivkovic their insightful comments, helpful guidance, and unwavering support thorough the entire process. I would also like to thank my co—author Jennifer Marietta-VVestberg for her assistance and knowl- edge about the SEC. My journey has been made more enjoyable because of my fellow students especially Ranadeb Chaudhuri, Gwinyai Utete, Bill Johnson, Iordanis Kara- giannidis, and Neslihan Yilmaz. I would like to especially thank Ranadeb not only putting up with my antics throughout our tenure, but also for being there through the toughest times. Simiarily, the support I have received from my parents, brothers and close friends has helped me perserve. Even though they have been physically far away, I feel that I have grown so much closer during my stay here in Michigan. I would like to give a special thanks to my wife. Dana, for putting up with all the long nights and reminding me that there is so much more to life than work. TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ............................................................ viii Blockholder Ownership and Corporate Control: The Role of Liquid- lty ......................................................................... 1 1.1 Hypothesis Development .......................... 4 1.1.1 Trade—off between liquidity and control .............. 6 1.1.2 Control through threat of exit .................... 9 1.2 Data ..................................... 10 1.2.1 Summary statistics of firm characteristics ............. 18 1.2.2 A measure of liquidity ....................... 21 1.3 Empirical results .............................. 23 1.3.1 Blockholder preferences ....................... 23 1.3.2 Liquidity and Preconnnitment ................... 26 1.3.3 Threat of exit ............................ 28 1.3.4 Loyalty, exit, or voice decision .................. 30 1.3.5 Blockholder Gains from Activism ................. 32 1.3.6 Blockholder choice of action and success ............. 34 1.4 Conclusion .................................. 35 1.5 Appendix .................................. 37 Employee Ownership of US. Institutional Investment Management Firms ..................................................................... 48 2.1 The Institutional Investment i\lanagt-nnent Industry ........... 54 2.2 Theory and Hypotheses .......................... 54 2.2.1 The Costs of Employee Ownership ................ 55 2.2.2 The Benefits of Employee Ownership ............... 57 2.2.3 Employee Ownership and Performance .............. 59 2.2.4 Employee Ownership and Risk Taking .............. 59 2.3 Data ...................................... 61 2.3.1 Employee Ownership of Institutitmal Investment. .\lanagement Firms ................................ 61 2.3.2 Institutional Inxr'estment l\lanagement Firms ........... 62 2.3.3 Portfolio Manager Ownership of Institutional Investment Man- agement Firms ........................... 64 2.3 1 Product Performance ........................ 66 2.3.5 Comprehensiveness and Survival .................. 67 vi 2.4 Determinants of Institutional Investment Management Firm Ownership ....................... 69 2.5 Portfolio Manager Ownership of Institutional Investment l\~Ianagement Firms ...................... 71 2.6 Employee Ownership and Alpha ...................... 74 2.6.1 IIM Firm Employee Ownership and Alpha ............ 74 2.6.2 Portfolio Manager Ownership and Alpha ............. 76 2.7 Employee Ownership and Risk Taking .................. 77 2.8 Conclusion .................................. 78 2.9 Appendix .................................. 81 Fraud and Registered Investment Advisers ........................... 96 3.1 Registered investment advisers (RIAs) .................. 98 3.1.1 Conflicts ............................... 100 3.2 Operational risk ............................... 103 3.3 Data ..................................... 106 3.4 Empirical results .............................. 110 3.4.1 Prediction of fraud ......................... 110 3.4.2 Investor Reaction .......................... 115 3.4.3 RIA reaction ............................ 117 3.5 Conclusion .................................. 118 Bibliography .............................................................. 128 vii 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 2.1 2.2 IO 03 2.4 iv 01 2.6 LIST OF TABLES Summary of block acquisitions ........... - ............ Summary statistics ............................. Principal component analysis ....................... Likelihood of being targeted by a blockholder .............. Determinants of the size of initial blockholding .............. Target Announcc‘n‘nent Cumulative Abnormal Returns (CARS) ..... Likelihood of Voice and Exit ........................ Blockholding returns ............................ Choice of blockholder action ........................ Summary Statistics ............................. Summary Statistics by Employee Ownership ............... Summary Statistics by Portfolio I\Ianager Ownership .......... Survival ................................... Determinants of Institutional Investment Management Firm Employee Ownership ................................. Determinants of Portfolio Managers Ownership of Institutional Invest.— rnent Management Firms .......................... viii 39 40 43 44 45 46 47 83 85 89 2.7 2.8 2.9 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.6 3.7 3.8 3.9 Employee Ownership and Alpha ...................... 90 Portfolio Manager Ownership and Alpha ................. 92 Employee Ownership and Tracking Error, Betas, and Standard Deviations 94 Summary .................................. 119 Consistency of RIA practices ........................ 120 DRP Summary ............................... 121 Probit .................................... 122 Probit by Firm Size ............................. 123 Negative binomial .............................. 124 Owner Probit ................................ 125 Flows .................................... 126 Key Person Turnover ............................ 127 Chapter 1 Blockholder Ownership and Corporate Control: The Role of Liquidity This essay examines a sample of outside blockholdings in US. firms to determine whether the liquidity of a firm’s equity affects the propensity of block shareholders to engage in activism. Theoretical work such as Shleifer and Vishny (1986) suggests that by purchasing a. significant block of shares a blockholder can overcome the free-rider problem inherent. in widely dispersed shareholdings. The relative 1‘)aucity of inter— vention by blockholders in the US. when compared to other countries like. Germany or Japan has led several scholars to cite the higher liquidity of US. securities as an obstacle to blockholder intervention. Their reasoning follows that higher liquidity low- ers the cost of exiting the position (Bhide (1993)) or increases the potential benefits from speculation (Kahn and Winston (1998)). These views neglect to consider why blockholders Would rationally establish the block in the first place. In a theoretical work, Maug (1998) counters that more liquid securities will attract more. blockholder intervention because blocks become. cheaper to acquire and higher liquidity allows the cost of intervention to be borne across more shareholders. The blocks are cheaper in more liquid securities not just. because of lower transaction costs, but because the higher liquidity allows blockholders not to preconnnit to monitoring. As disagreement. exists among theorists regarding the relation of liquidity and blockholder intervention. I examine liquidity’s on blockholder intervention empirically using a newly constructed sample of blockholdings in S&P 1500 firms from 1994-2005. The comprehensive nature of this sample also contributes to the literature on block- holders as prior work has focused on either a particular type of blockholder (e. g. 1,902 hedge fund blockholdings in Clifford (2008)) or only activist. events (e.g. 244 activist blockholdings in Bethel, Liebeskind. and Opler (1998)). The sample of 18,210 block- holdings includes both active and passive filings from all outside blockholders. The broad coverage of the sample is important as I find that. characteristics of the blocks such as size and level of activism vary with the identity of the blockholder and that certain types of blockholders tend to be more passive or active. Their tendency to either engage or refrain from activism correlates with regulatory and business con- straints. By using a well defined set of potential targets. the S&P 1500, I am able to avoid self—selection issues that other papers that only study the characteristics of observed blockholdings suffer. W ith this sample. I investigate whether liquidity increases the likelihood of new block formation. As liquidity of a firms equity and block stock holdings are. endoge- nously detern‘iined. I establish causality of the relationship using the change in tick size on major US. stock exchanges in 1997 and 2001 to help form an instrument. for liquidity. I find that liquidity increases the probability of block formation in my sam- ple. This result supports the theoretical claim that more liquid markets encourage the formation of blocks. As blocks will only form when the benefits of monitoring are higher than the cost. the result is consistent the conjecture in Maug (1998) that. higher liquidity leads to a higher socially improving level of monitoring. though such a conclusion is difficult. to support empirically without. observing the cost of monitoring and losses to other stakeholders. I then turn my attention to the set of observed blockholdings and examine the determinants of the size of the blockholders stake. The model in Maug (1998) implies that a blockholder will take smaller stakes in more liquid securities all else equal. The blockholder’s decision to perform costly monitoring is private information, so the higher liquidity allows the blockholder to engage in more informed trading with liquidity traders. Therefore, blockholders have a greater potential to gain when they are less precomnritted to monitoring as they can buy shares for a lower price that does not fully incorporate, the bt‘rnefits of their monitoring activity. As expected, I find that blockholders take a smaller initial position in more liquid securities. Besides encouraging activism by making blockholdings more profitable, I find that liquidity can enhance governance through the threat. of exit. If managerial compensa— tion is sensitive to the share price then blockholders can encourage managers to engage in share price maximizing behavior by threatening to sell their block, an event that. would punish managers. Illiquid securities reduce the credibility of the threat to exit since blockholders would receive lower prices for their shares. I show that firm value is enhanced in situations when the threat to exit is most credible - when managerial sensitivity to the stock price is high and when shares are liquid. This result contradicts the suggestion that liquidity lnrrts gm'ernance. I also look at existing blockholdings to see if illiquidity encourages blockholders to be more active rrrorritors of nranagcmcnt. Though I find that increasing liquidity increases the propensity for blockholders to exit. their position, I do not find any sup- )ort for illl(. uiditv increasing the ')1'() )ensitv to erre‘zwe in activism. Instead of exitin r l . I") t C") {'3 f3 or fighting management, blockholders of illiquid positions often choose a third option and do nothing. As building blocks in less liquid firms provides less opportunity to engage in beneficial monitoring and is more costly, investors will only do so when ex- pected returns from doing so are higher. I find that block holding return measures are increasing in illiquidity though blockholders with fewer constraints demand a smaller illiquidity premium. Finally, I show that. the liquidity affects the choice of nicmitoring action. This paper contributes to the literature by conducting an empirical test of the effect of liquidity on a blockholders decision to intervene. I provide evidence consistent with theoretical models that predict that improved liquidity will enhance monitoring by blockholders by permitting profitable action more often. I find no evidence that illiquidity forces institutions to monitor when exit is costly. Instead, I find that many blockholders are bound by regulatory restrictions or fiduciary responsibility and choose not to engage in shareholder activism. 1.1 Hypothesis Development Difficulties in contracting that arise from the separation of ownership and control as stated in Jensen and Meckling (1976) provide small atmnistic shareholders with little incentive to exert. control. They hear the full cost of monitoring to reduce agency costs and receive only a small portion of the benefits of their actions. The existing literature suggests that this free—rider problem can be overcome by the presence of a large outside blocklmlder. For example. Shleifer and Vishny (1986) present a model in which small minority shareholders in widely-held firms have little incentive to incur monitoring costs because each would like to free-ride on the monitoring of the others. but a blockholder can profitably take action if its stake. is large enough. Tln‘ouglmut this paper, I use this definition of monitoring - an action by an outside sharel‘iolder which can increase shareholder value relative to the value if the outside shareholder takes no action. This is similar to the definition adopted in Maug (1998) and makes no differentiation whether the action increases overall firm value or just expropriates from other stakeholders in the firm. In practice, these actions can take a variety of forms: engaging in conversaticms with management. starting proxy fights, “vote no" campaigns, the threat of selling the block, and even hostile takeover attempts. Blockholdings in public companies are commonplace around the world and are found frequently even in the relatively more dispersed US public equity market.1 Using a sample of 1.500 companies,2 Dlugosz. Fahlenbrach, Compers, and Metrick (2006) observe that the average firm in their sample has one outside shareholder that controls between 14-18% of the outstanding equity. Despite of this finding regarding the ubiquitous nature of blockholders, evidence of intervention by these blockl‘iolders is mixed. Clearly some blockholders, for instance wealthy activist individual investors, play an important role in gm'ernance.3 In recent decades. other types of instituticmal investors. such as pension funds and hedge funds. have also attracted media and academic attention for their activist actions (e.g. Smith (1996) studies a series of activist. interventicms by CalPERS). In contrast. Jensen (1989) notes that financial institutions and money management firms. which control over a. third of all corporate equity in the United States. are. typi- cally uninvolved in the major decisions and long—term strategies of the firms in which IFaccio aml Lang (2002) finds that in Western countries 92% of firms have at. least one. shareholder with at least 5% of voting rights. QThc sample taken from the Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC) covers about 90 of the value of the NYSE. AMEX. and NASDAQ markets and covers a set of firms and years similar to the sample used in this paper. 3For an example of recent. intervention by an individual blockholder. see (‘arl Ichann's recent involvement. with Yahoo!: http://blogs .wsj .com/deals/2008/O7/21/ what—can-carl-icahn-do-for—yahoo-now/ c/_ //‘f C}! they invest. Furthermore. more involved actions such as seeking board representation and engaging in proxy fights are rarer still. Jensen (1989) attributes this perceived passivism to a host of populist laws and regulations approved in the wake of the Great Depression, such as the Glass-Steagall Banking Act of 1933, the Securities Exchange Act of 1933. the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. and the Investment Company Act of 1940. Black (1990) suggests this passivity may be justified by the burden of legal obstacles that hinder rational action in all but extreme cases. Another frequently cited explanation for this lack of shareholder activism is that institutions would rather take the “Wall Street walk“4 - a colloquialism that implies selling a poorly run stock is much easier than dealing with management to try to in‘iprove the firm. 1.1.1 Trade-off between liquidity and control Given that blockholders may choose to exit from their blockholding when costly monitoring is needed. highly liquid markets may be a hindrance to effective corporate. governance by permitting blockholders an easier and cheaper exit. This view fails to consider that blockholders will rationally consider the liquidity of the security before choosing to form the block. Recent. theoretical work. such as in the model presented in Maug (1998). has countered that. more liquid markets may actually lead to more monitoring by blockholders as blocks become. cheaper to form and liquidity allows the cost of intervention to be shared with the liquidity traders. In response to a perceived need for iniprovement in an organize-ition. Hirschman (1970) suggests three possible outcomes: exit. voice. or loyalty. In the case of block ownership. the blockholder can sell their shares (exit). engage in activism (voice). or simply do nothing and maintain their position (loyalty). In this frmnework. a trade- "l'l'he oft—cited ““3,“ street walk" or "Wall street rule" traces its origins to guidelines published by the American Bankers Association in the Wills. 6 off occurs between exit and voice if the choice to remain loyal is not viable. Holding all else constant, as the cost of exit is lowered. exit becomes preferable to voice. Previous finance literature have suggested that. this relation is an important reason for why the US. market displays so little large shareholder intervention - highly liquid securities markets enable blockhtflders to cheaply dump under performing firms. Bhide (1993) argues that a natural trade-off between stock liquidity and active. investing is inevitable. Active shareholders could reduce agency problems by providing internal monitoring, but the act of monitoring makes these investors informed and thereby reduces the stock liquidity of their position owing to information asymmetry problems. Conversely, stock liquidity discourages internal monitoring by reducing the cost. of exit of unhappy shareholders. Bhide (1993) concludes that the public policy choices in the US. that have provided a very liquid stock market may come at. the cost of foregoing potentially valuable active investing. The cost of monitoring may also play an important role in which monitoring activ- ities blockholders choose. though inexpensive forms of monitoring may be ineffective. As Black (1990) states, some institutions face legal barriers against accumulating the size of the stake necessary to make value enhancing actions profitable. These legal rules were often intended to protect to mutual fund investms. Their ultimate effect is to render these blockholders inactive. Sin‘iilarly. Bolton and von Thadden (1998) argue that the liquidity of the stock market. will reduce activism as such liquidity encour- ages them to trade on private inforn‘iation. The incentive to speculate increases with the blockl'ioltlecs infcn'mational advantage over other investors. which will be higher in smaller more. opaque firms. These are typically the firms that are traditionally thought to need monitoring by blockholders the most. The above analysis does not take into account the blockholders decision to form the block. Kahn and Winston (1998) and Maug (1998) show that liquid markets can § help large blockholders overcome the free-rider problem. In particular, Maug (1998) presents a model in which the large stakeholder buys an initial position that is too small in the sense that the capital gain on the initial position does not cover the cost of monitoring. However. the ability to purchase shares on the open market at a price that only partially reflects the blockholders monitoring efforts gives the blockholder incentive to monitor. A larger toehold that would cover the cost of monitoring would precommit the blockholder to monitor. and thus prices would reflect this precommit— ment. By making the decision to monitor uncertain, the blockholder creates private information from which it can engage in informed trading. The blockholder gains most when other shareholders are most uncertain about whether the blockholder will mon- itor. The ability to make greater gains allows the blockholder to intervene profitably in situations with higher monitoring costs. This is the mechanism by which liquidity can enhance monitoring by blockholders. Higher liquidity may lead to a socially im- proving higher level of intervention (some stakeholders like managers with excessive compensation may be worse off). Liquidity allows the blockholder to share the costs of monitoring with the small shareholder through informed trading with them overcoming the free-rider problem. Since the blockholder"s decision to engage is costly and the blockholders initial stake does not precommit. them to monitoring, the blockholder can make profits by making the private decision to monitoring and then trading with the knowledge that their decision to monitor will improve firm value. The price of the shares will partially reflect the improvement in firm value that monitoring by the blockholder could provide. Therefore, the blockholder can choose to intervene and then buy shares that only partially reflect the full value of the blocklmlder‘s monitoring in'iproveinents. In order for this to occur, the. (.lecision to monitor must be not deterininistic. One plausible reason that. a blockholder would use a random strategy would be that the 8 improvements of the blockholder’s monitoring are known to all traders, but only the expected cost of monitoring is known. Once the blockholder takes a toehold, it receives a realization about the true cost of mcmitoring and then make its decision of whether to monitor based on this realization that is known only to the blockholder. Therefore, equity liquidity should enhance blockholders" ability to engage in costly monitoring as liquidity allows informed trading to spread the cost of monitoring among liquidity traders. As the cost to the blockl'iolder is lower, blockholdings will emerge in firms where the cost of performing monitoring would prohibit profitable blockholdings if the firm‘s equity was less liquid. Liquidity should also affect the choice of monitoring action. In Maug (1998), the author shows that a blockholder should be more concerned with effectiveness of the action than the cost in a. more liquid market since the cost can be shared over the liquidity traders. This gives me three testable implications. First, increasing liquidity should en- courage the formation of blockholding ceteris paribus. For a given monitoring cost, higher liquidity will allow the blockholder to spread more of that. cost to other passive shareholders as liquidity increases. Second. following the same logic, conditional on a block being formed, when liquidity is higher the initial stake taken by the blockholder will be smaller all else equal. Third. blockholders should choose more effective. forms of monitoring when the liquidity is higher. 1.1.2 Control through threat of exit Jensen (1989) suggest. that institutional investors are "remarkably 1‘)owerless: they have few options to express dissatisfaction with management other than to sell their shares and Vote. with their feet”. As .-"\dmati and Pfleiderer (2098) points out. exit. through the "V'Vall Street walk" is not. necessarily an alternative to activism. The threat of exit. may itself be a form of corporate governance. While managers might prefer 9 frequent turnover by institutional investors to large active investors that desire to serve on the boards to monitor and correct managers’ mistakes. managers would really prefer locked-in passive investors who do not sell their shares. If the liquidation of large block holdings has an adverse effect on the stock price, then managers who have much of their compensation tied to the share price either through stock or option holdings are credibly threatened by the possibility of exit by these blockholders. While this may not be monitoring in the conventional sense, the presence of the large blockholders can significantly improve firm value by encouraging managers to enhance shareholder value. This leads to another testable implication. As transaction costs impose a cost to exit, the effectiveness of a large shareholder’s threat to exit is increasing in market liq- uidity. In the Adrnati and Pfleiderer (2008) model, the discipline effect of a potential exit on the managers decision is increasing in the interaction of liquidity of the large shareholder’s position and the fraction of managerial compensation tied to stock per- formance. In Edmans (2008), the author presents a model in which privately informed blockholders remain even when exit is viable as a way to over myopic investment by management. In either model, the ability to exit enhances the value created by the blockholder. Therefore. I expect to see firm value enhanced when blockholders buy stakes in firms they can credibility use this threat against - firms with high levels of liquidity and also high managerial compensation sensitivity to the share price. 1.2 Data The initial sample consists of block share acquisitions of Strl’ 1500 firms by outside. blockholders between 1994 and 2005. Prior work has focused on either on a. particular type of blockholder or only activist events. Bethel. Liebeskind, and Opler (1998) 1 0 survey activism by all types of blockholders in Fortune 500 companies. Several recent papers study US. hedge fund activism using Schedule 13D filings. For the period 1998 to 2005, Clifford (2008) studies 1.902 sets of block acquisitions (both active and passive) by hedge funds, focusing on the stock price reaction and changes in operating performance. Using a sample of 194 Schedule 13D filings from 2003 to 2005, Khein and Zur (2009) examine entrepreneurial activists (both hedge funds and non—hedge funds). but focus on confrontational activism ignoring passive filings. With a sample of 1,059 Schedule 13D filings from 2001 to 2006. Bray, Jiang. Partnoy, and Thomas (2008) find that hedge fund activists are typically successful in the majority of their activist attempts. I limit my sample to 8851’ 1500 firms for two reasons. The first is a. data constraint. I need information on managerial stock ownership which I obtain from Standard and Poor"s Executive Compensation Database (Execucomp) for some of my empirical tests. The second is that I need a well-defined population, so that. I can also observe which firms do not. have blockholdings. While the S&P 1500 represents 87 percent. of the total US. equity market capitalization, the sample selection may limit the applicability of some of the results to other samples. Using a more extensive sample, Cadman. Klasa, and l\*Iatsunaga (2007) find Execucon'ip firms rely more heavily on aggregate financial performance measures, such as earnings and stock returns to determine CEO cash compensation. As the stock incentive effect is integral in order for the threat of exit to provide discipline, this threat. may be less credible in iniii-Execuemnp firms. “'hen a person or group of persons acquires beneficial ownership, that. person must. file a Schedule 13D with the SEC. Beneficial mvnership is defined by the Securities and Exchange commission (SEC) as voting power or investment power (direct. or indirect. power to sell the security) of more than 5% of a. voting class of a company’s equity. Schedule 13Ds must. be filed with the SEC within 10 days of an entity obtaining 5% 11 or more of any class of a company’s securities. Alternatively, the filer can submit the short-form, Schedule 13G, which is intended for passive investments. By filing the Schedule 13G, the filer (i.e. l')lockholder) cedes the right to effect. or influence the control of the target.5 The penalties engaging in control purposes after filing a Schedule 13G can include losing the right to vote any stock in excess of 5%, loss of profits and even criminal sanctions.6 Filers must update Schedule 13D upon changes in the position, while filers of Schedule 13G must update their holdings only once a year. I use the required subsequent filings (Schedule 13D\A or 13G\A) to determine the post-acquisition changes in holdings. To construct my sample, I obtain 407,809 Schedule 13D and 13C filings and their amendments which have S8513 1500 firms as targets. These filings are available on the EDGAR website7 for the years 1994 through 2005. The 407,809 individual filings correspond to 20.684 target-blockholder pairs and give a time-series evolution of each blockholding. I define the holding period as the period from initiation of the block until the blockholder reports a shareholding less than 5% or is no longer required to report (i.e. when holdings drop below 5%). In cases in which multiple blockholders file together on the same Schedule 13D, I consider only the lead filer. This choice should not affect inferences since the group members should share the same incentives. In my study, I focus on outside block ownership and do not include managerial and employee stock ownership since managers and employees may have additional economic interests other than their interest. as shareholders. For example, ownership by managers mayr have conflicting influences on firm value and agency costs. Man- E’Though passive filers may be eligible to file the Schedule 1358. the Schedule 13D is the default filing. Since a filer has to petition the SEC to file as a passive investm', filers that do not. choose to do this will file a Schedule 13D even if they have no intentions of engaging in activist activities. “For an example of a legal case in which an investor failed to disclose a control purpose as required see Gulf f3 Western Industries. Inc. 1!. Great Atlantic 63 Pacific Tea Company. Inc. 7http://www.sec.gov/edgar.shtm1 12 agers may value consuming perquisites or keeping their job even when they should be replaced at the cost of other stakeholders, particularly shareholders. Jensen and Meckling (1976) propose that ownership by managers can help align incentives and reduce agency costs. Ernpirically, Morck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1988) find that while small levels of managerial ownership reduce agency costs, high levels of managerial ownership can serve to entrench management and reduce firm value. Similarly for rank and file employees. the relation between ownership and firm value is not clear. Ownership by rank and file employees could better motivate. and align interests. Kim and Ouimet (2008) show that small employee share ownership plans (ESOPs) may increase firm value, while large (i.e. greater than 5%) ESOPS do not increase firm value. A large ownership stake by employees may allow them to extract unearned benefits at the expense of other stakeholders. Consistent with this explanation, Faleye, l\r‘Iehrotra, and Morck (2006) document lowered investment, poor performance and decreased firm value in firms with large ESOPs. As the interests of managerial and employee block ownership are ambiguous, I exclude them from my analysis and focus only on outside block ownership. The mixed empirical evidence of the effectiveness of outside blockholder activism is not that surprising considering all blockholders do not face the same set of con- straints. The ability to take advantage of liquidity may only hold for certain segments of blockholders. Cronqvist and Fahlenbrach (2008) show that. blockholders are not a hon'iogcneous group. Some blockholders appear to influence corporate behavior while others seem to passively seek their preferred behavior. One explanation is that. some entities, such as hedge funds, have few restricticms and can pursue whatever policy their Inamigers see. fit. while other entities face binding institutional constraints. Even for a single entity. the act of acquisition of shares above certain ownership levels may impose constraints. For example. the Exchange Act Section 10(1)) requires that. block- 13 holders that own more than 10% of a share class report their sales and purcl‘iases every month and forfeit. profits made from "round trip" transactions. This effectively reduces the short-term liquidity of the position. Certain histituticmal investors face a variety of regulatory barriers and potential conflicts of interest that make active monitoring difficult, if not. impossible in many cases. Legal or regulatory restraints may prevent some regulated financial firms from accumulating the necessary size block that. makes monitoring cost effective. For in- stance, a diversified fund, as defined in the. Investment. Company Act. of 1940, may hold no more than 5% in any one comI.)any, and not more than 10% of any firm’s outstanding shares. These constraints are binding for many investors. An investment by the Fidelity Magellan mutual fund of only 0.05% of its portfolio is sufficient to buy the maximum 5% ownership stake in the smallest Stk'P 1:300 firm. Biolase Tech. Inc. (as of August 21, 2008). Likewise, conflicts of interest may exist when mutual funds consider activism against current or potential clients. Davis and Kim (2006) use proxy voting to show that mutual fund companies are less likely to vote against those firms with which they have a business relaticm. Simila‘irly. pension funds are typically bound by ERISA or “prudent man” regulation. This forces pension funds to only hold prudent securities limiting their investment opportunity set. Also, “prudent investor” rules require high levels of diversification. Given the constraints to holdings, these financial blockholders may find exiting or remaining 1')assive more attractive than try- ing to acquire. a large enough stake in the firm or forming a coalition of like—minded sharelmlders to cover the costs of performing monitoring. Like financial blockholders. non-financial (_)1‘_)erating companies may establish block- holding in other firms. which I will call corporate blockholdings for the sake of brevity. A large (and somewhat inconclusive) literature exists on the merits of diversification strategies by such firms. Corporate bloc‘kholders may also seek other benefits when cs— 14 tablishing a blockholding. In a. sample of over 10,000 customer-supplier relationships, Fee. Hadlock, and Thomas (2006) studies a firm’s decision to invest in trading part- ners. They find equity stakes can often help overcome contractual incomple'tem‘iss and also help provide quasi-inside financing to ease financial constraints of trading part- ners. The presence of these intense trading relationships between firms may mitigate the incentive to provide discipline. Kang and Kim (2006) show that the relatedness of the acquirer and the target is an important determinate of blockholder interven- tion. They find relatedness negatively impacts action as blockholders do not want. to damage business ties through heavy—handed governance. Borokhovich, Brunarski, and Parrino (2006) find that outside blockholders who do not have current or potential business connections to a firm are perceived to be better monitors of management than outside blockholders with such connections. Though corporate blockholders face these conflicts of interest, they are typically free from ownership level restrictions unlike fi- nancial blockholders. Corporate blockholders can and frequently do exercise control through complete corporate control. Partial stakes are often a precursor to takeover attempts. Kyle and Vila (1991) suggest that liquidity enables the formation of a toe- hold stake necessary for profitable hostile takeovers. Overall, corporations may face lesser regulatory constraints than financial firms7 but business relationships between firms may limit aggressive monitoring activity. Activist. investors such as hedge funds and individuals are typically free from the regulatory barriers and conflicts of interest. that limit activism by financial firms and corporations. Recently, hedge fund activism has been a hot topic both in the media and acaden'iic literature. Unlike mutual funds. hedge funds can take much larger undiversified positions since they are. not. subject. to the Investment Act of 1040 that stifles activism by mutual funds. Bray. Jiang, Partnoy, and Thomas (2008) note that hedge fund managers typically have strong i1‘1ce1‘itives to generate returns and often require investors to "lock-up" funds for long periods of time allowing greater flexibility in trading. \Vhile the academic literature tymcally focuses on hedge funds as a special type of activist, the clizu‘acteristics attributed to them are not unlike those of wealthy individual investors. Entrepreneurial investors, such as Carl Ichann, Ronald Pereleman, George Soros. and \Varren Buffet t, can and frequently do acquire blockholdings and sometimes engage in activism. I combine both individual and hedge fund entities in the Individual/partnership category for a variety of reasons. First. there is no generally accepted definition of a hedge fund.8 Since the main issue of this paper is to examine the effect of liquidity on governance by blockholders, lumping individuals with hedge funds is natural since both face a similar lack of constraints on their ability to engage in activism. Among the distinguishing features of hedge funds mentioned in prior literature are highly incentivized managers. lack of regulation. ability to take concentrated undiversified positions, and the use of derivatives and leverage. Clearly, most. wealthy individual investors have extremely similar features. Khein and Zur (2009) also note that both hedge funds and activist individuals are both relatively free from regulatory controls of the Security Act of 1933, the Securities and Exchange Act of 1934, and most importantly the Investment. Company Act of 1940. Other categories of blocklmlders such as church plans and endowment are harder to classify cleanly into any of the aforementioned categories. To cover blockholders that do not natural fall into the financial. corporate and individual / partnership categories, I create a category called other. On one hand. these blockholders may be exempt. from the legal restrictions that apply to financial blockholder and the conflicts of interest that emerge in corporate blockholdings. However. these entities may have many other 880e, http://www.sec.g()v/spotlight/herlgt‘funds/hetlge—vaughn.litm for a variety of opinions and definitions. 16 self-imposed or social oriented constraints. I exclude from my block formation sample filings from trusts. estates and foun- dations that represent the passing of an already established block from one owner to another.9 Similarly, I exclude filings reporting ownership in a. new company which was formed from an existing company in which the filer had a blocklmlding (e.g.. a merger or spin-off). I use the Compustat Execucomp database to find directors and executives of target firms. I then compare these with the filing to eliminate insider blockholdings from the sample. The use of the Execucomp dataset limits my sample to the years 1994—2005 and coverage of firms in the S&P 1500.10 Since blockholdings must be reported only if the filer owns at least. 5% of the target, this restriction limits the amount of l)lt’)(‘-l£o< Ndmm 3&3de vabfi EN snowman gamed 959:» manna: airman 2:55; 033m A 953 A mm? :osmxca 9532552 .9: 95:22 ESE; 3:5 BEE \Escmficfi 3m.:i.50 Erozcih om? 035.2% 309:5 >5 >..§::::m waxy—o: xuoflm “m Ezcm ox.m..m :5ch 15:}: omnw $3.5 $3.2 1:5. coda “Kafm Kkndm worm 1.3de cmmd .239 .mt—E—rfictzo 539 £923.; .rztc No.3. 9.536 fivwfim wnd 055.3... wmfié mazzéicaza $152315 Qamm REV: Kmmhm 8.: cavmwm mum; 3545.50 swam. $09.0 $8.2 owns oxsvmh 3%.: :Einm $555: as? flags sea A $2 A songs 9: mass—OE 15:: 1.5:: 73:; eczemaom LET. iazcm .8~€-:E.EE me 23% m9? $335333 .3 552255 9:33; #335 ”4. 7.5.an 326$sz mo mmoaasm - a. :8: mfifioaeu 5m mzoflosbmfi Unmm Sm 52:22:; 2: .53 .3253: 5.58:: 0:76: a 3 sawiafim mmeimza mammmzommfi 59a $23 £533.. 23. .Q2 Bfioozom 2: :o $3.893 mm Humbug i: we .E..:::.....:::E 2: RE :33: mczmba i fix: megs? 529283 93 $23 2:55 2:on A3258 5mg: 0: :omfimom 2: .25 @5553 925 1.995.; a 8:2: as: moot ho exaum can £5 a 339.: 3293003 2: 3:: 30:32: cam mfi 25888 EEOJVEOE BE .22: 855 $5 vi mix: UmEEHBmv mm S .Ec: mm x003 a 3.39: we $255: of mm :3ch 9583i #3565303 mi 13 «53.5%: mewzfisosma 9:23:33 2: com: @953 mm was. :ofiamoa N835 “NEH. ADM; @Etmfiom :0 NH Eon: HOV Q2 Ezthom do 3 :5: 8 95:5sz $2334.53 2: :0 women E 3?...3Easkbesfiaiesfl was .853ch .32: mo uo< EEQEOD “:25ng 8 goofinzfiv $323.5.“ SE mazoiixscf .3 :ossofimmflu 2a. .5322253 wcgsvoe 22 \3 Q2 33?: 2: :o ~5me 5:13 3.52% 035 mEH .m<0Qm .3 cigars; .n: mfiSEEEEs :2: EB mEE Um; can QM: mzéezom OWm Eoc ESEwEGom 4.53 .5 225% 2: :2:an _ .nocm «:5 2:: 2.5.5.5 :2: 33...; Loaf. k2,: E .231. $533.3.“ .5 New. c. 7.5.5:: #2: .CE 2: 4.575 E mzitiiooc .rzzEC—EE away: .t. 33:31. tats: 2:. mnomfimmzvom x903 mo enemas—Sm HA 2an 39 m; 2:. a: 22 3:: mm; 82 :2 22 22. 32...: 2:: 93.1%.; :3 8.0 a 2; 3:: o. a; S: a S; :52 33-0 imam- :5- :53- Soc- 3%: 83. mg: 2:: 25.3- ES- Eng: 39.3.3 5%.: :3 33 $3 $8: 2.3 £3 3: £3 £3 EN: 25255? ......fl.2 :3 25.0- 33. ES: .33.. Sod- ES 25¢. 83. 22: 95.55.5110: $3-9 9:32 5:132 532 Z 5:102 932 Z :5:sz 562 Z wo:o$§fl 130% 9250:. mfimmwm .18mi1:-%£m~.:1:: v.5 13.95500 50.: $33.81, .593 :< Afifiom + 51.1% + BUAMZOV 8.5 HOLMZO 13251 7:830 + 85:3 * moth * 8.8 m0 03.3 1:: mm 8093 9:511an 1:m Smmpcmwhum E mm 1.25.91 m: 2.1: 1:11:35 .3325 mo 35:: :00: + 333E111 mm 12:111 31: mwfgfl :00: 1322.8: 53:15 2: m: umgmamm Aways»: 13wm§<<flr§mm mm 12501 Emma: :0 53m: 139:1: 53:15 93 mm 8:35chng .ufim:9:oO 3 13.5%: we. :ozdxzxfiacu .1329: :00: Q5 EEEmwOH 9: mm 38 “SISEmS .Amoomv :2:qu 1:1. :an £89.50 5 188mm: .3. V815 3:5:950 2: m: $15-D 638:me t 52 2:12am 9: :o v :5: 3 @2095: 23 1:: 12a 3:1158 mo :93 13:3 :0 1.94:: 2:.va 1:: mfiwfii 0:: £093 95% 5320 H .oom 1:: 3.3 50315 m:o§mmsvow 8.3.» :83 ENE :0 3093 WD 0:615 31m mo @7125: 29:% 2E mfiumfidum huwaasm NA 23:8 40 Raw Va: QNH Mtcm gmfiv 035:?» m0 :OSpOQOum :3 go 2.0 :1 :0 $32520 mg 80. Ed 95 2:0- gammy? ”3 33 and- So 3:. mags/.360 20. Ed no mod $5 $23 £6. and- 2:0- $3 8.3 3&0 3.0 mg- mg. mg moo 255% :5 fig Em EN 3 5:0:09000 Emmczflm ”m 702.0% 23. 3.0- 34:- :5- 2.0- 30. 30. one 2.0 a: of E: 22533022.3.5 8.3- mg. mg- 30 mg 3.0 m3 Sc 8.0- 3.? and- ”we- aéamvmfi ”no 2: :5 :0 3o :0 2.0- :0- mac- :5- and- :3. 0515.530 5.0- Ed- mad- 8.9- mg- 23. 2.? woo 3.3 o: m: a: ”$200 3.0- was- 33. :3 3o :0 8.0 :0 mg mg mg mg 3.20 and- mod- mod 30 so 3o- 80 mod owe .80 one 2.9 3554 mcom wcom mesa moon Hoom coca amafi wamfi baofi mmafi mamfi vmmfi wofin—SE‘Q/ .mfifimdvzm mo mwflom QSFH n< Ecxmnw 01.00% x0005 003030. 23 mo 0m0$>0 330005 2: m“ Qqaeafimnfix mmmo 50b 33300. 955.5 m0 0§30> .3200 $5005 0%. mm 0533/ 00:0Q .Soomv #0005303 80¢ @5005 m0 $00 0350mm m0 302500 mnfiU 93 mm 33.0 A3005 wfivmuoa 0:0 5 was: 553 0.8a m0 00500005 9: .00 002900 .fl 305$ .A0~.:30> 9:00ng .00:0Qv\_:.5§m~_\/ * 0:3 m0 A330 fifiv wEmzv 0m0.§§ .3502: 2: - Amcomv ~:::E< E m: 10:23. E ~5fi§v~ .3057. mi: E 01.: H 3:53: w: 7.0.5.535 «5.: 2: .3 .Efig»: km??? 0.: 1.209: < ESL mmmbmam 30:09:00 3&0:th m4 2an 41 Table 1.4 Likelihood of being targeted by a blockholder This table reports the estimates of an instrumental variables probit model. The sample consists of 195,984 firm-month observation of 88:? 1500 firms between 1994 and 2005. The dependent variable, Block, equals one when a new block is formed in a particular firm-month and zero otherwise. Illiquidity is the first principal component of the liquidity variables as defined in Table 1.3. Performance is the industry adjusted return on assets defined as EBITDA/ (lagged assets). log(market cap) is the logarithm of book market capitalization as reported by Compustat. Leverage is the industry adjusted book leverage ratio defined as debt / (debt + book equity of equity). G-Indezr is the Governance index as reported in Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003). Constants are included in the model but not reported for brevity. Standard errors are clustered by target firm. The symbols *, ** and **" denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Spec 1 Spec 2 Spec 3 Illiquidity Block Illiquidity Block Illiquidity Block Decilnalization —5.53*** —4.25"* -3.59*“ * (l/P) (3.18) (3.09) (2.36) Eighths * (l/P) —4.29 -12.73*** -13.90*** (0.86) (6.74) (9.84) (l/Price) 12.01“ 1801*“ 1839*” (2.31) (9.90) (14.46) Illiquidity -0.00 -0.05*” -0.05*** (0.01) (3.70) (3.48) Performance. —().08 -0.29*** -0.18 —0.21** (0.38) (3.95) (0.70) (2.65) log(market cap) -0.44”* -0.10*“ -0.58’”* -0.08"* (20.50) (11.37) (18.38) (6.67) Leverage 0.54“M 015*” 0.52“” 0.09” (6.55) (4.13) (5.26) (2.08) G-Index 0.01 0.00 0.03“M 0.00 (1.37) (0.10) (3.42) (0.67) Mgr Own % 0.02“M —0.01*” (9.46) (6.00) Observations 157.763 157 765 131.174 131.171 69.577 69.577 R2 0.24 0.57 0.00 \Vald test 8.01 14.98 7.87 \th > \‘3 0.0046 0.0001 0.0050 Table 1.5 Determinants of the size of initial blockholding This table reports the estimates from a Tobit model where the dependent variable is the ownership percentage as recorded in the initial blockholding filing (i.e. Schedule 13D or Schedule 13G), the lower bound is 5% and upper bound is 100%. The initial sample of 14,027 blockholder acquisitions in which the filer that obtains a 5% or greater stake in any S&P 1500 firm between 1994 and 2005. Illiquidity is the first principal component of the. liquidity variables as defined in Table 1.3. Active means that the blockholder states that it pursues action by the management of the target as reported on the Schedule 13D. The actions range from discussing business strategy to a hostile takeover attempt. (See the Appendix for SEC instructions for reporting Item 4 - Purpose of Transaction) Performance is the industry adjusted return on assets defined as EBITDA/ (lagged assets). log(market cap) is the logarithm of book market capitalization as reported by Compustat. Leverage is the industry adjusted book leverage ratio defined as debt / (debt + book equity of equity). G- Indez is the Governance index as reported in Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003). Standard errors are clustered by target firm. T-statistics are in parentheses. Constants are included but not reported. The symbols *, ** and **" denote significance at. the 10%. 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Spec 1 Spec 2 Illiquidity Size Illiquidity Size Illiquidity 1.01 1.366 (2.75)*** (2.26)** Decimalization * (l/P) -2.47 —3.220 (2.65)*** (6.05)*** Eighths * (l/P) -4.93 -1.627 (1.04) (0.75) (1 /Price) 7.30 2.77.5 (1.45) (1.13) Active 0.164 6.393 (3.31)*** (13.48)*** Performance -0.445 0.199 (1.90)* (0.29) log(market cap) -0.651 0.906 (25.65)*** (2.20)** Leverage 0.812 -0. 430 (7.41)*** (0.71) G-Index 0.015 -0.104 (2.00)“ (4.()4)*** \Observations 14.027 14.027 9.546 9.546 43 weed wood 25¢ 25.: See :5: See :5: E. 3&2 3.2 93.2 mewfi Sea 3.2 95.2 woman massassflc :2: :9: 25.8 80.3 as: 34.3 fine sea was as- 2.0. 8.: Be Se 9:. 23 33.25 :23: 3...:va 1.3.3 1.34.3 m2. 8s E Q: ..._E_.é. 32.5.3 £33 .1993 as: :Lfle 32s. a 123.3 gene as- Ed. 2d. no.0- and- a3- 2:- :5. 3V .. 3 figs $25.3 2;: 8.0.3 isms 2%.: :5: 9a.: and. m2- 8:. mod. 42. as- was- 3.9- E c.3285 38.5 icon 2%.: as: 1.23.3 tend e4: read was- :3- Ed- 2.0- go. 3.5- :e- was- 3 56:52:. SENES 813-526 3356 2445.0 258-450 82.21.50 335.0 2.755 ..».E>Eu.ime.~ £75.: ex; :2: RE. (53 2: fit. eibtomEmfi 323: .1; was .1. .... £0357? ESL .memezéoemm E was murfifixmé. .Amzzom + .mfixem + HULmZCV .35 HUQMZC tissue AmsosaO + 3.5sz * 82m * 5.8 m0 035 9: me $003 £59:an Use Emmmtmwemm E 30. Ezcec E 2%: as.\§e.e.:~ .553 Eviea was me. 532 wen—aways e3? ammo 2: cm: H .935 2036833 #53 2: 95ch .936 S @338 E35 52?: we as: mazes: com ms? #255 noise: e5 eueEsmm H .3505 ”Boreas on... ma? £532 BEE: $.58an 05 8.59:8 fl .Ecousuexm E 63.5%: flew QEmSEpo 3:93:55 gm: $5 meow was «6.3 seesfime 9535863 chasm x003 www.mH we mumwmzoo 295?. 3H. AmmaflUV mafia—mm _wauo:£< o>$fl§550 unoaeunsonndw uewumfl win 2an 44 Table 1.7 Likelihood of Voice and Exit The sample consists of 278,987 blockholder-month observations in which the blockholder ini- tially files a Schedule 13C. The dependent variable equals “voice” if the blockholder switches to a Schedule 13D filing, “exit” if the blockholder reports a ownership level less than 5%. The omitted case is if the blockholder continues to be passive (filing the required Schedule 13G every year). Cumulative return is the stock return since the initial blockholder filing. Age of position is the number of months since the initial blockholder filing. Change in size is the change in percentage of shares of the target owned by the blmtkholder from the initial fil- ing. The classification of blockholders into Financial, Corporate, and Individual/Partnership is based on the blockholder response to Item 14 on Schedule 13D (or Item 12 on Schedule 13G). Standard errors are clustered by target firm. Constants are included in the model but not reported for brevity. The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at. the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Spec 1 Spec 2 Voice Exit Voice Exit Illiquidity 0.16*** -0.06*** -0.068 -0.139*** (2.79) (6.49) (0.67) (10.00) Cumulative return -0.029 -0.020 (0.41) (1.20) Age of position (months) 0.015 -0.001 (1.60) (0.73) Change in size ‘70 0.036 -0.0428*** (0.73) (5.56) Corporate 1.056* 0708* * * (1.83) (12.3) Individual/ partnership 1688* * * 0.269** * (4.23) (2.69) Performance -4.139*** -0.378** (4.88) (2.17) log(market cap) —0.308** -0.146*** (2.51) (10.5) Leverage —0.181 0136* (0.33) (1.93) G—Index -0.041 -0.002 (0.56) (0.37) Observations 278.987 278.987 198.647 198,647 Pseudo R2 0.001 0.001 0.012 0.012 45 25.0 ES 118.3 omd 5.: :3 “Shawna 3.9- $22.3 .23 flood 3mg: ***Aw©.mC cad isms 8.0- :35 mod- *meflv So 83 32: figs So 82: No.3- A53 :3- ***Awm.wv a: wood 95.: :22.me mmd $5.3 .2; £33 2.3- :me3 no.3 mood 32: ***:m.mv wed A38 Hmdu $.78 mad- ***Amm.wv DNA” need 893 ***A©H.omv and ***:h.wv cod NE 253$»;er fizfiéav Miuzxfim ~5C¢SECD 3517:: 93(12: FEEH Tvzmfihfiisblza “Z 322::x:c.Y:cZ * 2:62.72: EUEEE g g E 5 E E IZ~.~C .HCCL 39$? 2; ~53 :bzi ~r512::ngsaz I.» 2.22;.“ 72.5; 35.1.: 533.5%?“ £75.: N; fizz ”KB. .33 E: p: 3.525537. £23:me NEH APE fifibfi KS Uohflmio Em ESE EE‘EEm .02: mo 54‘ €251.35 2: >3 $5.551 .3: wagogxooi 0.6 Egatmccuzoz A02 Estonom so NH Em: .Hov Om; Escoaom no 3 Eu: 3 95592 $305303 2: :0 ~53; .£. as.£m§§fidn~§d§32€£ was £95er90 ”38:65,“ 9:: 98392003 mo :OEmoEmmfio 23L .Uevgufi PS :8» a3; 2: 5.5 9:8:r5fai mfifimmmv: firs .055 Eco 6 5:38 5 .532 @2th 95:0: wepmsgw $4.55 2: mw 293.23, Eofizeauv 2: .n 1:5 w £5515 :H .532 @02va wEEon >8“ o5 fl 223:3 ”EmwchmU of pm; .3538 5 55m, >575 305 €03 m5 :2?» 3% 3a of U21. fizz:52:32:: €33 2: .3 33. 3: E: :3 .552; Ammo $2.53... 2: mix: #55 2: we 4:3 .2; £25.: fists: $522; it _.;::~.::... H mafia—emu wfigoaxoflm m4 mzmfi 46 Table 1.9 Choice of blockholder action The sample consists of 1,297 blockholdings in which the blockholder initially files a Schedule 13D requesting a change in company action. I use a multivariate logit model in which the dependent variable equals “CEO” if the filer requests a change in chief executive officer, “merger” if the filer requests a completion or rejection of a proposed merger, and “other” if neither (the omitted case). Performance is the industry adjusted return on assets defined as EBITDA / (lagged assets). log( market cap) is the logarithm of book market capitalization as reported by Compustat. Leverage is the industry adjusted book leverage ratio defined as debt / (debt + book equity of equity). G-Inder is the Governance index as reported in Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003). The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Spec 1 Spec 2 CEO Mergers CEO Mergers Illiquidity 0.02 -0.13*** 0.16 -0.129** (0.13) (3.62) (0.56) (2.14) Performance 2.67 0.83 (0.68) (1.05) log(market cap) -0.04 -0.07 (0.11) (0.99) Leverage 1984* -0.45 (1.67) (1.36) G-Index -0.01 -0.02 (0.10) (0.62) Constant -4.24*** -().31*** -3.96 0.35 (13.26) (5.39) (1.32] [0.64] Observations 1.297 832 Pseudo R2 0.01 0.012 Success rate 75% 50% 73% 65% 47 Chapter 2 Employee Ownership of U.S. Institutional Investment Management Firms 48 Institutional investment management firms are the single largest category of in- vestors in the U.S. equity market. These firms manage portfolios on behalf of insti- tutional clients such as pension funds, university endowments, and charitable founda- tions. As of December 2005, institutional investment management firms (11M firms) managed $5.8 trillion worth of U.S. equities, almost a. trillion dollars more than the second largest category of investors, mutual fundsl. Despite the massive amount of wealth controlled by these firms, surprisingly little academic research has focused on this industry. Although IIM firms all offer the same primary service, delegated portfolio man- agement, many different organizational structures coexist within the industry. One structure which varies widely is employee ownership2. Slightly over half of the firms in this industry are wholly employee owned, 29% have no employee ownership, and the rest are partially employee owned. In this paper, we address the questions: Why do so many different employee ownership structures coexist among firms providing similar services? Does the variation in employee ownership structures predict performance or investment behavior? \Ve take an optimal contracting approach to answering these questions. We view employee ownership as one tool IIM firms use to reduce agency problems with their employees. Of course, Il.\l firms can use other incentives to motivate their en'iployees. They will select employee ownership only when the benefit of employee ownership outweighs the cost relative to alternative incentives. We identify variables measuring these costs and benefits and analyze the determinants of employee ownership. 1There is some double (bunting between these two categories of investors. Many mutual funds out.— source portfolio management to IIM firms. For example, Vanguard markets the Vanguard \Vellington Fund. Stock selection for this fund is outsourced to \Vellington h'lanagement Company. The Van— guard fund is counted as part of mutual fund assets. and these assets are counted again as part. of \Vellington’s assets. 2Throughout this paper we use the term ownership to refer to ownership of investment manage~ ment firms. We do not use this term to describe the holder of portfolio securities. 49 \Ve begin by examining aggregate employee ownership at the firm level. Consistent with an optimal contracting equilibrium, employee ownership is lower when it provides less benefit, which we measure in several ways. First, when many people contribute to the success of the firm the free rider problem is greater and the incentive effect. of employee ownership is weaker. \Ne find strong support for this argument. En’iployee ownership is decreasing in the number of professional employees, the number of invest- ment styles offered by the firm, and the amount of assets under management. Second, one benefit of employee ownership is that it reduces the need for firms to monitor employees, but this benefit is small when the cost of monitoring is low. Consistent with this idea, employee ownership is lower in firms with a large proportion of indexed funds. Our next step is to look within firms, and examine several factors which predict individual employee ownership. First, we find that portfolio managers who manage a. large proportion of their firms’ assets and portfolios, and thus generate a large pro- portion of their firms’ profits. have higher ownership. Second, when an employee has multiple roles within the. firm, ownership will be an attractive incentive, because it. re.- wards the value maximizing allocatitm of effort across tasks. Consistent with this idea, we find that portfolio managers who are also firm executives have significantly higher ownership. Third, en’iployee ownership creates a. strong link between the firm and the employee. This is less costly when there is low uncertainty about employees’ quality. we find that portfolio managers with longer tenure have higher ownership. Fourth, ownership provides a. coordinating incentive that encourages cooperation within firms. W’e find that portfolio managers wlmse investment. style overlaps with their firms” dom- inant style have higher mvnership. which we interpret. as due to the benefits of creating an incentive to share information and methodologies. These results hold even after including firm "fixed effects. If firms and employees optimally allocate ownership, then employee ownership will not predict performance. If employee ownership predicted performance. then firms would alter their ownership structure and clients would alter their investment flows to eliminate the outperformance. However, because ownership rarely changes shocks to the economic environment may have resulted in suboptimal ownership structures. This does not appear to be the case. Consistent with equilibrium, we find no relationship between firm level employee ownership and risk adjusted performance. After control- ling for firm characteristics, there is no evidence that portfolio managers’ ownership of HM firms predicts performam1e. Employee ownership alters firms’ risk taking incentives in two ways. First, em- ployee ownership reduces risk sharing decreasing employees’ incentive to take risk. Second, employee owners are less likely to be terminated, reducing their career con- cerns and increasing their ability to bear risk. We test which of these effects dominates by regressing portfolio risk on employee ownership of IIM firms. The results Show that portfolios managed by employee owned firms, and portfolios managed by individual employee owners, have higher tracking errors, betas, and standard deviations. Even after including firm fixed effects, rmrtfolios managed by employee owners have higher risk. Our work contributes to the literature on agency problems in delegated portfo- lio management. Most of the existing literature has focused on the agency problem between portfolio management firms and investors. For example. Almazan, Brown, Carlson, and Chapman (2004) show that explicit investment. restrictions are. a sub- stitute to other control mechanisms used to protect. investors. Chen. Goldstein, and .liang (2008). Del Guercio, Dann. and Partch (2003), Khorana, Tufano. and Wedge (2007), Meschke (2006), and Tufano and Sevick (1997) show that mutual funds boards' characteristics explain fee setting and restructiiring decisions. Deli (2002) empirically examines mutual fund contracts and finds that variation in fund fees is consistent with rational contracting. While there have been many studies of the agency problem between investors and portfolio management firms, there has been far less research on agency problems within portfolio nn-inagement firm. Clearly these agency problems are linked. To minimize agency problems with investors. portfolio management firms must control their employees. The earliest studies of agency problems within portfolio management firms, Chevalier and Ellison (1999) and Khorana (1996) focus on the role of career concerns in aligning e1111')loyees' interests with the firm. Specifically, they show that. poor performance leads to termination. Gervais. Lynch, and Musto (2005) derive a model explaining these. empirical findings. They assume that mutual fund families are better informed about portfolio managers (uiality, and they can credibly signal their information to investors by terminating some portfolio managers. In addition to disciplining portfolio managers through termination, investment management firms can reward en'iployees for good performance. Kempf and Ruenzi (2008) find that relative performance within mutual fund family results in risk shift.- ing, which they attribute to competition among portfolio managers for promotion and access to resources. Farnsworth and Taylor (200(5) survey portfolio 111anagers about compensation. They show that performance based bonuses are widespread. Interest- ingly, bonuses are usm—illy discretionary rather than formula based, and investment performance is not the prinmry determinaiit. Khorana. Servaes, and Wedge (2007) show that mutual fund manages who invest. in their own funds have positive risk- adjusted 1')erformance. Our paper continues this line of research on agency problems within portfolio management firms. \Ve make several novel ("outributions. Most importantly. this is the first study of the role of employee ownership in portfolio manageu‘ient companies. Employee ownership is related to firms' economic structure and investment behavior, and is widespread but it has not. received any prior academic attention. This is also the first study of agency issues within the institutional investment management industry. More generally, our results contribute to the literature on employee ownership and its role in controlling agency problems. There is an old debate in the finance literature on the effect of employee ownership on performance. McConnell and Servaes ( 1990) and Merck, Shleifer, and Vishny (1988) argue that employee ownership of publicly traded corporations has an observable effect on firm value. On the other side, Demsetz (1983), Demsetz and Lehn (1985b), and Himmelberg, Hubbard, and Palia (1999) argue that competitive pressure forces firms to optimally allocate ownership, and that employee ownership varies depending on its costs and benefits. Further, they believe that any observed relationship between ownership structure and firm value is the result of an omitted variable bias caused by failing to include factors which affect ownership. Our results are consistent. with the optimal allocation of ownership within firms, and we do not find a relationship between employee ownership and performance. Our sample includes a large number of private firms, and so we observe a much greater range of en‘iployee ownership than previous studies. The final contribution of our paper is that we provide a. detailed description of the structure and organization of institutional investment. nn-magement firms. The few prior studies of HM firms have. primarily focused on performance persistence. Busse, Goyal. and VVahal (2007). Christopherson, Person. and Classman (1998). Coggiu, Falmzzi, and Rahman (1993) and Lakonishok, Shleifer, and Vishny (1992) all find evidence of HM firm performance persistence. Del Guercio and Tkac (2002) focus on fund flows rather than performance persistence, and show that the performance fund flow relationship is linear for lll\l firms. \Vith our focus on employee ownership we r 03 provide a far more. detailed description of the structure IIM firms than prior papers. 2.1 The Institutional Investment Management In- dustry Like mutual funds, institutional investment. management (HM) firms provide del- egated portfolio management services to their clients. However, IIl\I firms differ from mutual funds in several important ways. First, mutual funds directly own their port- folios. and mutual fund shares represent claims on these portfolios. IIM firms provide security selection services, but typically their clients directly own the securities. Sec- ond, IIl\=‘I firms have large minimum im'estmcnts, and their clients are institutional investors and wealthy individuals. Third, unlike mutual funds, the portfolios do not have a board of directors to protect investors’ interests, and there currently exists little SEC regulation. All IIM firms offer their clients portfolio management products. whicl’i represent security selection services in a specified investment style. Frequently, within a product each clienth assets are held in separate accounts. A product’s performance is a. value- weighted composite of the constituent accounts. Each account in a composite will hold the same portfolio. subject to some variation resulting from differences such as social responsibility screens and diversification restrictions. 2.2 Theory and Hypotheses Ownership structures vary widely in the. institutional investment management i11- dustrv. Our U‘oal is to understand whv this \vl'ariation occurs. and its relation to in- u ('5 t... . vestment behavior. To examine these questions. we use an optimal cmitracting per- spective. We view employee ownership as one tool IIM firms use to align employees’ interests with the firm. In equilibrium, IIM firms and employees will jointly determine ownership by trading off the costs and benefits, while also considering alternatives. The IIM industry is highly competitive for two reasons. First, the barriers to entry are low. Second, clients can withdraw funds under management. The combination of these two factors creates strong product market competition. Fama and Jensen (1983a) argue that firms with the lowest cost structure will be the ones to survive competition. Failure to efficiently solve agency problems will result in higher prices or worse performance, and eventually firm failure. To survive, IIM firms must. optimally allocate ownership. 2.2.1 The Costs of Employee Ownership Fama and Jensen (1983b) and Demsetz and Lehn (1985b) state that employee ownership is costly because it requires risk-averse employees to hold undiversified portfolios. As a result, equity is worth substantially less to employees than to di— versified outsiders. Eirij;)l(1)yee ownership may also distort incentives and encourage employee owners to invest in low risk projects to reduce their personal risk, even if these investments are inferior. Empirically this implies that, all else equal, firms with lower risk will have higher employee ownership3. As many of the firms in our sample are private, we do not directly observe firms' equity price volatility, and we do not directly observe profits. However. profits are a. function of assets managed4, so the volatility of a firms assets under management will be strongly correlated with firm risk. 3Another important consitleration is that emplm’ees' ('mttside wealth should influence their will- ingness to own their employer. Unfortunately we cannot observe employees wealth. 1l\lost firms are coimwusated as a percentage of assets under management. Many firms also offer clients the option of paying partially through incentive fees. Ci“! (4’! Employee ownership provides a strong incentive when a small number of individ- uals control the key decisions that determine firm performance. However, Fama and Jensen (1983a) argue that when decision making is dispersed throughout the firm, the incentive effect of ownership is diluted, and free riding will occur. As decision making becomes increasingly dispersed throughout the. firm, individual specific incen- tives such as salary and bonuses, become relatively more efficient. Thus we expect. employee ownership to decrease as the number of business segments, employees, funds, and breadth of products offered increases. Employee ownership reduces or eliminates a firm’s ability to terminate an em- ployee. This is not entirely a bad thing. Chevalier and Ellison (1999) Show that fear of termination causes portfolio managers to herd. By reducing the probability of ter- mination, en'iployee ownership helps to create the correct ex ante incentives. However, ex post, once a firm has acquired additional information about an employee’s skill, the option to terminate is valuable. Because employee ownership makes termination costly or impossible, it reduces the firms options. When the firm is certain that an empkryee's quality is high. it is less costly to give up the option to terminate the em- ployee. Since the firm learns about employee quality over time, employee ownership should be higher for employees with long tenure. Lakonishok, Shleifer, and V ishny (1992) show that the HM industry is composed of two segments: a small set of large firms which offer generic products and compete by offering low costs and stability, and a large number of small boutique firms offering specialized niche products. Economies of scale are more important for generic low cost products. Since high employee ownership limits firms ability to raise. exterue-tl capital, we expect that. employee. ownership will be low for large firms offering generic products and high for small specialized firms. r .36 2.2.2 The Benefits of Employee Ownership The most obvious benefit of employee ownership is that it creates an incentive to exert effort. Of course there are other incentives, such as bonuses. profit. sharing, and career concerns. \V-r expect employee ownersl‘iip to be high when the benefits of employee ownership are high and the costs are low relative to alternatives. Relative to other incentives, an advantage of employee ownership is that it correctly aligns employees’ incentives with the firm. This will be especially important when employees have multiple roles within the firm, and the correct allocation of effort across roles depends on employees information. This information asymmetry will weaken other incentives. Bonuses will be inefficient because the firm does not know how the employee should allocate their effort, and profit sharing will cause employees to trade long term value creation for short term profits. Fama and Jensen (1983a) argue that when decision rights and decision control are held by a single individual it is optimal for them to have ownership. As a result, we expect. employees who manage multiple portfolios or who manage the firm to have higher employee ownership. In the previous subsection, we stated that. employee ownership is a diluted incentive because its value depends on the actions of all employees. However, this can be beneficial if the firm needs to coordinate employees actions. There is evidence that cooperation within portfolio management firms is important. Farnsworth and Taylor (2006) show that firm perforn'iance has a larger effect on bonuses than individual performance in HM firms. Pomorski (2008) shows that. information sharing between mutual funds within a family is impm'tant, and that. information sharing is higher when funds have similar styles. Since information sharing is more valuable for products with similar styles. we hypothesize that that employee ownership should be higher when a. firms product offerings are. concentrated in a narrow range of investment styles. Fama (1980) argues that career concerns will align employee interests with the firm. 5? However, Holmstrom (1982) shows that when effort is unobserved and output is noisy, career concerns will usually fail to fully align incentives. For example, career concerns diminish close to retirement resulting in reduced effort. Morrison and Wilhelm (2004) develop a model of partnerships, which closely resemble many of the HM firms in our sample. In their model, firms benefit when senior employees mentor young employees to transfer soft skills. However, because mentoring is unverifiable and noncontractible, senior employees will underinvest in mentoring. Employee ownership is a solution to this problem, as senior employees can sell their equity to the younger employees at retirement5. The price paid at retirement will depend on the retirees’ prior investment in mentoring. Because employee ownership can be sold at retirement, it provides an incentive for older employees. Empirically this implies that longer tenure employees will have higher ownership. Employee ownership is the only incentive that does not require external monitor- ing. This implies that ermiloyee ownership should be high when there are large benefits to aligning incentives and external monitoring is difficult. Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2008) and Cren‘lers, Driessen, Maenhout, and Weinbaum (2006) argue that monitor- ing is more valuable and more difficult when products hold risky assets, actively trade, and have high turnover. Thus, we. expect to see higher employee ownership for firms i'nanaging portfolios with these characteristics. Cremers, Driessen, Maenhout, and \N’einbaum (2006) also argue that there are economies of scale in portfolio monitorine, which suggests that employee ownership will be higher for firms with less assets under 111anagement. ”Ai‘iecdotally, we are told it is common for retiring employee owners to sell their equity to junior ermiloyees. We thank Steven M. Levitt of Park Sutton Advisers for helpful discussions on this point. 2.2.3 Employee Ownership and Performance Does employee or portfolio manager ownership reliably predicts performance? In— tuitively it seems that employee ownership and skill should be p(;)sitively related. Port- folio managers who know their skill is high will form their own firms and existing firms will offer their most skilled employees ownership. However. this does not necessarily imply an observable relationship between employee ownership and alpha. If employee ownership is optimally determined in equilibrium, two forces will pre- vent employee ownership from predicting performance. First, if employee ownership caused outperformance competition would cause firms ”to alter their ownership struc- tures until the outperformance was eliminated. Second, clients select firms based on expected net..-of-fee alpha. Even if employee ownership predicts, but does not cause outperformance, it would affect fund flows. Berk and Green (2004) show that if there are decreasing marginal returns to scale in portfolio management, then in equilibrium clients will allocate money to firms with predictably positive alphas until expected alpha is zero. Given that Chen, Hone. Huang, and Kubik (2004) and Pollet and W il- son (“2008) show that mutual funds have diminishing marginal returns to scale, this suggests that fund flows will eliminate performance predictal’nlity. However, employee rarely changes and fund flt.)ws may not fully eliminate predictability and so we test if employee. ownership predicts performance. 2.2.4 Employee Ownership and Risk Taking Fama and Jensen (1083b) argue that risk-averse enmloyee owners will choose to reduce firm risk, because of their undiversified holdings. However, employee ownership reduces or eliminates firms ability to terminate employers. which (flecreases employ- 59 ees’ career coneernsG. Prior studies show that mutual fund managers’ career concerns affect portfolio risk. Chevalier and Ellison (1999) show that younger managers. whose termination-performance relationship is stronger, take on less unsysternatic risk and hold more conventional portfolios. Khorana (2001) shows that following poor perfor- mance, portfolio managers increase portfolio risk prior to termination. These papers suggest that employee ownership will affect risk taking, but the direction of the re- lationship is unclear. Ownership will increase employees’ rewards from positive out- comes. But for negative outcomes the ownership has two competing effects: employee owners will suffer direct losses if their firms’ products underperform, but they have lower career concerns. Whether higher potential rewards and lmver career concerns outweigh potential capital losses is an empirical question. There are two types of investment risk affecting IIM firms: asset price volatility and tracking error. Since fees are based on a percentage of assets managed, revenue will fluctuate along with asset prices. Firms can control this risk by managing their portfolios’ betas and standard deviations. Fund flows are heavily influenced by perfor— mance relative to a. benchmark as shown by Del Guercio and Tkac (2002) and James and Karceski (2000) show that institutional funds have. a linear 1)erft)rmance—flow rela- 7 tionship and underperforming a benchmark results in significant outflow-rs. Portfolio managers can reduce the risk of outflows by tracking the benclnnark closely. 6In our san'iple. we find a. very strong negative relationship between employee ownership and terminatitm. for both key personnel and port folio managers. Results are available from the authors upon request. 7Del Guercio and Tkac (2002) and James and Karceski (2006) show that the perforniance— fund flow relationship is linear for IIM firms’ products. We find a similar result in our sample. 60 2.3 Data We use two datasets in this study: a. panel of Form ADVs8 filed with the SEC, and the PSN Database produced by Informa Investment Solutions. All IIM firms with at least $25 million in assets under management are required to file Form ADV9. Firms must file Form ADV at least annually and more frequently if there are material changes to the. firm, including changes to owners controlling more than 5% of the firm. “7e have a panel of all Form ADV filings from 200010 through 2006, including the filings of defunct firms. This panel should be comprehensive and survival bias free, because firms are legally required to file Form ADV. The PSN database11 is designed for plan sponsors and consultants to identify potential asset managers. It contains information on investment performance as well as firm and portfolio characteristics. Although the PSN Database begins in 1979, we use only the portion that overlaps with our Form ADV data from 2000—2006. 2.3.1 Employee Ownership of Institutional Investment Man- agement Firms \Ve obtain information on employee ownership of HM firms using informatimi from SEC Form ADV. Schedule A of Form ADV requires each firm to list all direct owners with a stake greater than 33% as well as all executive officers and directors regard- “Active IIM firms’ most recent Form ADV filings are available at. : http://www.adviserinfo. sec.gov/IAPD/Content/Search/iapd_0rgSearch.aspx. UIntentional misstatement, deliberate omission, or failure to file Form ADV is a federal crime. In practice, criminal prosecution is rare and firms are brought into compliance by the threat of legal action. “’VVe have all FOl‘lll ADV filings from January 1, 2000. However. firms can file as little as once per year. and so we use Form ADV information from the beginning of 2001 to be certain our sample is complete. llBerzins and Trzcinka (2005) and Del Guercio and Tkac (2002) use Mobius Group's :\l—search database. In 2000 Informa Investments purchased and integrated the Mobius database into the PSN Database. 61 less of ownership. Each owner is required to list their title or status within the firm. Schedule B identifies indirect ownership, which is common as many employees own equity through layers of trusts and holding companies. Both schedules report own- ership by categories rather than exact percentages. \V'e impute ownership using an algorithm described in the Appendix. Because non-executive owners with less than 5% ownership are not required to report, we do not observe ownership stakes below 5% for non—executives. However, we will observe employee ownership that represents meaningful control rights over firms’ operations. Employee ownership of firms is common in the institutional investment manage- ment. industry. Table 1 Panel A shows 72.07:. of firms have employee ownership greater than zero. 'We include three measures of employee ownership: the. largest position, the sum of the three largest positions, and total employee ownership. The summary statistics are calculated conditional on employee ownership greater than zero. Clearly, employee ownership is concentrated. The average largest position is 56.8%, the average top three positions is 78.2%, and average total employee ownership is 89.5%. \l’e also look within firms, and measure individual portfolio managers" ownership. By combining Form ADV data with portfolio manager names from the PSN database to identify portfolio managers who are also employee owners. Table 1 Panel A shows that 17.5% of the products in the sample are managed by portfolio managers with at least a. 5% ownership stake in their firm. Conditional on non-zero ownership, the average portfolio managers ownership is 52.1%. 2.3.2 Institutional Investment Management Firms Table 1 Panel B shows there are 1.118 firms in the intersection of the. Form ADV sample and PSN database. Table '2 Panel A shows the firms divided into four cate— gories: zero employee ownership. minority employee owned. majority employee owned. 62 and wholly employee owned. The majority of firms are wholly employee owned and 28.8% have no employee ownership. l\‘lajority employee ownership is about twice as common as minority employee ownership. Table 2 Panel A shows that firms with zero employee ownership have far more professional employees and manage more separate products. l\r-‘Iinority employee owned firms have moderately more professional employees and products than majority and wholly employee owned firms. From Form ADV we. (_)bse.1've if firms have additional business segments engaged in the following business activities: broker-dealer, registered representative of a broker dealer, commodity trading, real estate, insurance, banking, and other financial prod- ucts. we calculate the variable, Other Business Segments, as the sum of the number of additional business segments. Index (76 is the percentage of the firms’ assets under management in index products. Table 1 Panel A shows that very few firms offer iii- dex products. This segment of the market is dominated by a few large firms. Firm Portfolio Turnover is the value weighted annual turnover across a firm’s products. We measure the homogeneity of a firm’s products with the variable Style Herfind- ahl. This is the sum of the squared percentage of total assets under management invested in each equity style. We use 12 equity style categories based on four size categories: all, large, mid and small, and three style categories: value, growth, and core. The average Style Herfindahl is 0.89 indicating that most firms focus on a narrow sector of the equity market. Style Herfindahl is higher for employee owned firms. Form ADV requires firms to list additional services provided to portfolio clients from the following list: financial planning, pension consulting, selection of other ad- visers, publications of periodicals or newsletters. security rating or pricing services, market timing services, and other. N on—Portfolio Services is the sum of the additional services prm'ided to portfolio clients. The majority of firms in our sample do not 63 provide any additional services. Average assets under management is $17.8 billion but this figure is highly skewed, median assets under management is only $1.2 billion. Table 2 Panel A shows that firms with zero employee ownership are much larger than the other firms. Minority employee owned firms are considerably larger than majority or wholly employee owned firms. Equity is the largest component of assets under management. and more than half the firms have only equity products. Employee owned firms are more focused on equity products. Table 2 Panel A shows that employee owned firms manage fewer international products, more small cap products, and marginally fewer core equity products. 2.3.3 Portfolio Manager Ownership of Institutional Invest- ment Management Firms In the combined PSN and ADV sample, we obserye all portfolio managers who own at least 5% of their firm. Table 1 Panel C shmvs there are 3,118 distinct. portfolio managers in our sample, who on average manage 1.9 products. Key Person is an indicatm' variable that equals one if a portfolio manager is also an executive officer of the firm. Table 1 Panel C shows that. 18% of portfolio managers are also executive officers. Table 3 Panel A shows that portfolio managers who are also executive officers are more likely to have an equity stake in their firm. We include two variables to measure the importance of a portfolio manger within the firm. Proportion of Products Managed is the. number of products managed by a. portfolio manager divided by the total number of products offered by their firm. Pro- portion of F irm’s Assets Managed is the total value of assets controlled by a portfolio 64 manager divided by the total value of assets managed by their firm. Table 3 Panel A shows that. both of these variables are higher when the portfolio manager is an owner. Tenure is the number of years the portfolio manager has been at the firm. Table 1 Panel C shows that on average portfolio managers have been at. their current firm for 10 years. Table 3 Panel A shows that portfolio manz-igers with an ownership stake have longer tenure than non-owners PM Index is the proportion of assets managed by a portfolio manager in index products. Very few portfolio managers control index products. PM Turnover is the portfolio managers’ value weighted average turnover across the products they manage. Table 3 Panel A shows that portfolio managers with an ownership stake have lower t.1_1rno\-'er. We. include two variables that measure the similarity between a. portfolio managers products and their firms products. PM Style Complement is the percentage of the firm‘s total assets under management in the same equity style as portfolio Iiianagers products. For example, if a portfolio manager controlled a single small cap value port- folio, and 35% of the firms assets under management were invested in small cap value products, this variable would be 0.35. For portfolio managers with multiple products it is the value weighted average across their products. P:\1 Asset Class Complement is calculated in the. same way, but measures the asset class overlap between firms and portfolio managers" products. Portfolio managers with an ownership stake in their firm have higher values of both variables. Table 3 Panel A shows that pcn‘tfolio managers with an ownership stake usually are more focused on equity, but the differences in equity style are not large. These results are generally consistent with the firm level findings. 65 2.3.4 Product Performance The product returns reported in the PSN Database are a composite of returns on clients’ accounts. Accounts within the same product. can have different returns for a variety of reasons, such as social responsibility screens and diversification criteria. A products” return is a value-weighted average of all an IIM firm’s accounts with a similar investment style”. The SEC checks reported returns during random audits of IIM firms. Table 1 Panel D shows summary statistics of the returns reported to the PSN Database. The mean monthly return is 0.72%. To risk adjust returns, we use two variations of the Carhart (1997) four factor rnodell3. Bit = (ii + v‘lfli(R./l[f — th) + fiQiSJl/[Bt + [.337inllth + 4,134Z‘PR12t + (it (2.1) In the first version, denoted Forward Carhart Alpha we estimate the Carhart model over the 24 months following the measurement of ownership. We also estimate a. one period Carhart alpha as: (lit 2 Return” — [ti-llijylt — th) +j321'81'lth +1332ijl-[Lt +f3421PR12tl (2.2) where the coefficients are estimated using data from the previous 24 months i.e. t- 24 to t0. As a robustness check, and because it is common practice in industry, we include benchmark adjusted abnormal returns”. We calculate this benchmark, denoted as Russell alpha. as the geometric mean return on the fund over the 24 months ”PM the rules governing the calculation of composite returns see http://wwwgipsstandards. org/. 13Factor returns are from Ken French's webpagc. ”we assign each fund to one of 12 size/style groups. There. are three styles: core. growth, and value, coupled with four size groups: large. mid, small. and all. Vt’e use the appropriate Russell size/style index except for large core, where we use the S&P 500 index. as the PSN reports that the S&P 500 is the most widely used index for this group. Russell Indexes are the most common benchmark for all other groups. 66 after measuring ownership, minus the geometric mean return on the appropriate style matched index. Table 2 Panel C shows that the returns and alphas are similar for firms with different. levels of employee ownership, and Table 3 Panel B shows returns and alphas are similar regardless of portfolio managers’ ownership of their II.\‘I firm. 2.3.5 Comprehensiveness and Survival The fact that participation in the PSN database is voluntary may create two prob- lems: selection bias and survival bias. Selection bias will occur if firms’ decision to participate in the PSN database is correlated with characteristics of interest. To ex- amine this issue, we compare the PSN data with statistics from the Conference Board (2007) report. We take the percentage of the total U.S. equity market managed by all institutions and subtract off mutual fund and hedge fund holdings. The remainder is IIM firms’ holdings. and direct. stock ownership by insurance companies, pension funds, and endmvments. PSN firms manage 90% of this remainder. Because the remainder contains direct ownership by other institutions, it should be larger than the value of funds managed in the PSN database. Since the unexplained remained is relatively small, it is suggestive that the PSN dataset is reasonably comprehensive. Because particij'mtion is voluntary the PSN dataset may contain a survival bias. There are three forms of survival bias: backfilling, liquidation bias, and non-reporting. Liquidation bias occurs if the terminal returns reported for a fund do not include the terminal returns from dissolving the fund. Non—reporting bias occurs when a. firm strategically ceases reporting following poor performance. As discussed in Busse, Goyal, and \Vahal (2007). the PSN database has not. permitted backfilling since 1994. We use only post 1901 data. in our sample and so backfilling is not an issue. In their study, Busse, Goyal. and VVahal (2007) examine the PSN database and conclude that it does not have a. meaningful survival bias. 6 ‘sl Table 4 Panel A shows summary statistics of armualized firm level survival. On average 3.5% of firms cease reporting each year. We divide disappearing firms into two categories: cease filing Form ADV, and continue to file. The majority of firms that exit the PSN dataset also cease reporting to the SEC, suggesting that they have genuinely not. survived. I-Imvever. each year 1.3% of firms exit the PSN database. while continuing to file Form ADV. It is possible these firms cease managing institutional money but continue other activities requiring them to file Form ADV, so 1.3% is an upper bound on the firm level survival bias. Even if some surviving firms exit the PSN database, this will only bias our results if exit is correlated with employee ownership. The differences in survival across ownership categories are not statistically significant. Table 4 Panel B shows summary statistics of annualized product level survival. Product exit, is lower than firm exit because large firms have more products and higher survival rates. In an average year, 1.8% of products exit the PSN database. Slightly over half of these cases occur when the. firm managing the product exits the PSN database, but 0.7% of products exit while the managing firm continues to report other products to PSN. Unfortum-rtely there is no way to determine if the firm has genuinely closed the product or if the product. still exists and is not reported. The non-survival of products in this dataset is lower than that of mutual funds reported in Carhart (1997). suggesting that non-sm‘vival in this dataset. is relatively low. Once again, the differences in survival across ownership categories are not. statistically significant. Studies examining performance persistence are concerned about. survival because performance has a strong negative correlation with survival. As a result, survival bias causes researchers to overestimate persistence. Our focus is employee ownership and so our concern is whether there is a relationship between employee ownership and survival. To test this relationship. we regress non-survival on employee ownership using a random effects panel probit model. The dependent variable equals one if it 68 is the last period the product reports. The results in Table 4 Panel C show that the relationship between employee ownership and non-survival is not. significant. Given the absence of backfilling, the similarity between non-survival of HM firms mutual funds, and the fact that ownership and non-survival are uncorrelated, we conclude it is unlikely that survival bias affects our results. 2.4 Determinants of Institutional Investment Management Firm Ownership Table 5 examines the determinants of NM firm employee ownership. We use three definitions of employee ('iwnership: the largest position, the sum of the three largest po— sitions, and total emj')loyee ownership. Because employee ownership is bound between 0% and 100% we use a. random effects panel Tobit model. The logarithm of the number of professional employees is negative and statistically significant. in all specifications. This result is consistent. with the idea that when many employees contribute toward the value of the firm. ownership‘s incentive effect. is diluted. Since each employee receives a smaller benefit from their effort. free riding occurs. For all models. a one standard (l("\'1‘(1l1()11 decrease in the number of professional employees implies an increase in employee ownership of greater than 20% relative to the mean. The logarithm of the number of products and the Other Business Segments index are also included primarily as measures of firm focus. Concentrated employee owner- ship is lower when there are many products. as the number of products grows firms either disperse equity across more. employees. or avoid employee ownership entirely. Other Business Segments has a significant and positive relationship with the largest employee ownm'ship position, but is insignificant in the other two specifications. 69 There is a clear negative relationship between employee ownership and the per- cent age of a firm's assets under management in index products. There are several very good reasons for this. First, the cost of monitoring index products is very low. Index funds are simple and trz‘msparent, the portfolio managers task is clearly defined, and performance is easy to evaluate. When the costs of alterimtives to employee ownership are low, employee ownership will be low. Second, the transparency and simplicity of index funds implies very strong product market competition, reducing the need for other incentives. Third, there appear to be large economies of scale for index funds. This segment of the market is dominated by a relatively small number of large insti- tutions. Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (“2008) and Cremers, Driessen, Maenliout, and VVein- baum (2006) argue that portfolio turnover is related to the need for external moni— toring. High turnover implies both greater portfolio manager discretion and higher external monitoring costs. suggesting that employee owned firms will have a competi- tive advantage in high portfolio turnover strategies. However, the data do not support. this argument. There is a significant negative relationship between employee owner- ship and 1.)ortfolio turnover in the first column. and no relationship in the remaining two columns. \Ve include two \v'ariables that measure the scope of the firms’ operations. Style Herfindahl is a l’lerfindahl Index of each firm's investment styles. Non-Port folio Ser- vices measures the number of additional services that the firm offers to its portfolio clients. Each v:-u'ial')le is weakly significant in one specification, but. overall these vari- ables have little significance. The logarithm of total assets under mane-igement. is highly significant. Firms managing more money have significantly lower employee ownership. This effect is economically large. If the logarithm of total assets under management (-lecreases by one standard deviation it implies an increase in employee ownership of 70 between 15%1—35‘70 relative to the mean. This negative relationship is unsurprising. First. one way a firm becomes large is by taking in a large amount of external equity. Second, the larger the firm the more difficult it is for any one individual employee to have a large. impact. on firm performance. Third. Almazan, Brown. Carlson, and Chapman (2001) and Cremers. Driessen, .\laenhout. and \Veinbaum (2006) find evi- dence of economies of scale in mutual fund families monitoring of funds, suggesting that the relative costs of alternatives to employee ownership decrease in firm size. The remaining variables all control for the type of investment products the firm offers. The results show that broad based employee ownership, shown in column three is associated with equity investment. But there is no relationship for closely held firms. Possibly this suggests that. it. is easier for employee owners to bear undiversified firm risk when this risk is spread across many employees. The clearest result is that employee owned firms invest far less in core equity products, and specialize in either value or growth products. 2.5 Portfolio Manager Ownership of Institutional Investment Management Firms In this section, we examine which employees within IIM firms have ownership. Because of data limitations we limit our focus to portfolio managers. If a portfolio manager controls multiple. products they are aggregated. resulting in one observation per portfolio manager per year. The first column of Table (i is estimated using a random effects panel Tobit model. The second column is estimated using a linear _ . . f' panel regression model wrth firm level fixed cffectsl'). l‘i’l‘arainetric panel Tobit models with fixed effects are not, consistent. Semiparametric models for panel Tobit fixed effects are available only when the fixed effect is for the unit of observation. Since we estimate fixed effects at the firm level. and not the portfolio mam-iger level, the semiparametric models are not applicable. 71 Key Person equals one if the employee is a key person as defined in Form ADVIG. Key Persons have responsibility and control over the entire firm. Since they affect overall firm profits. the incentive effect of equity is not diluted. Further. employees who are portfolio managers and Key Persons have multiple roles within the firm. It would be extremely difficult to write a compensation contract specifying the allocation of effort between portfolio management. and firm nn-magement. Equity ownership solves this problem, and rewards the correct allocation of effort. The Key Person variable is highly significant even with firm fixed effects included. In the Tobit model, the results suggest that Key Persons have ownership stakes about 16% higher relative to the mean. When fixed effects are included the implied effect is larger. implying a key person has an ownership stake 75% higher relative to the mean. We include two closely related variables: the proportion of the firms’ total assets under management controlled by the portfolio manager, and the proportion of the firm’s total products controlled by the portfolio manager. When either variable is high the portfolio manager has a large effect on overall firm profitability. As predicted, the results show significant positive relationships between both variables and ownership. The implied effect. of these variables is relatively modest in the panel Tobit, a one standard deviaticm decrease change in these variables results in decree-ises in portfolio manager ownership of 2.5% and 0.5% relative to the mean. However. the implied effect is much larger in the firm level fixed effects regressions. For both variables, a. one standard deviation decrease is associated with more than a 25% decrease in portfolio manager ownership relative. to the mean. There is a strong negative relationship between the logarithm of firm total assets under management and portfolio manager ownership in the Tobit regression. This is lbForm ADV defines key persons as: Chief Executive Officer. Chief Financial Officer. Chief ()pera— tions Officer. Chief Legal Officer. Chief Cmnpliance Officer. director, and any other individuals with similar status or functions. consistent with economies of scale in portfolio monitoring. The results state that a one standard deviation change in a firm’s assets under management is associated with 3%-4% higher portfolio manager ownership. Once firm fixed effects are. included this variable is not significant. Portfolio mangers with long tenure have significantly higher ownership. There are many reasons to expect this result. First, it is less costly for the firm to eliminate its option to terminate long—term employees as there is less uncertainty about ability. Second, employee ownership makes it significantly more costly for the firm to terminate a portfolio manager, increasing tenure. Third, portfolio managers with high tenure likely have greater wealth, increasing their capacity to bear the risk of a large position in their employer. Fint-illy, skill or some other third variable may drive both tenure and ownership. In the fixed effects regression a one standard deviation decrease in tenure is associated with a 15% decrease in employee ownership relative to the mean. W'e include PM Index % and PM Portfolio Turnover as measures of the cost of external monitoring. The results are significant and negative for both variables in the Tobit regression. The result for index fund management is consistent with our hypothesis that ownership is lower when there is less need for monitoring. However, the negative result for portfolio turnover was not predicted. Once firm level fixed effects are included, neither variable is significant. We include two "\yr'ariables to measure the overlap between portfolio managers’ prod- ucts and their firms’ products. The results show a strong positive relationship between portfolio manager ownersl'iip and the ccmiplement of their equity style with their firm. The firm fixed effects regression suggests that a. portfolio manager whose style comple- ment. is one standard deviation below the mean will have 9% less ownership relative to the mean. These results are consistent with Pomorski (“2008), who shows that there are greater benefits to sharing information when portfolio styles overlap. Portfolio 73 manager ownership is higher in firms which manage primarily ecuiity. However, once firms’ asset class focus is controlled for with fixed effects. portfolio managers with both pure equity funds and balanced funds are more likely to be IIM firm owners. We include controls for the asset class and investment style of the portfolio man- agers’ products. The panel Tobit regression small cap portfolio managers have higher ownership. Once firm fixed effects are included neither style or market. cap is related to portfolio manager ownership. 2.6 Employee Ownership and Alpha Beginning in this section we limit our sample to U.S., actively managed, equity products. Most prior empirical results in the managed funds literature are for equity products, and so restricting our sample allows for greater comparability with the existing literature and established benchmarks. We test if employee ownership predicts performance using both firm level employee ownership and portfolio manager ownership. For each product, we estimate alpha us— ing the three benclunarking nrethods discussed in subsection 3.4. We use two methods to test for significance: pooled OLS regressions with standard errors clustered by prod- uct and size as reconmiemled by Petersen (2009), and Fama—hIacBeth regressions. We also forrrr equally weighted portfolios of products based on firm and portfolio manager ownership and estinrate the Carhart (1.007) alpha. we include the logaritlnns of firm assets under management and product. assets under nranagement as control variz-rbles following the results of Chen. Hong. Huang, and Kubik (2004). 2.6.1 IIM Firm Employee Ownership and Alpha Because several authm's have argued there is a. non-linear relationship between em- ployer-r ownership and performance for publicly traded companies i.e. Morck, Shleifer. T-l and Vishny (1988) and l\/‘IcConnell and Servaes (1990). we measure firm level employee ownership with a series of indicator variables”: Minority, Majority, and Wholly Em- ployee Owned. Table 7 Panel A shows some of the coefficients on employee ownership are, signifi- cant. But it is very difficult. to argue that there is a consistent or meaningful pattern of significance. ()f the. alpha estimates. forward Carhart alpha is the most precisely es- timated. Employee ownership and forward Carhart. alpha are not significantly related in the clustered regression and one coefficient is significantly negative in the Fama- MacBeth regressions. For the other alphas there is some positive significance between employee ownership and alpha, but exactly which ownership level is significant varies across the specifications. Perhaps most striking is the small size of the estimated coefficients. Most coefficients represent only a few basis points per month and so in addition to sporadic statistical significance there is little economic significance. There are three sets of portfolio regression results in Table 7 Panel B. The first row shows the alpha from Carhart regressions run on firm employee ownership sorted portfolios. The alphas are insignificant for all pm'tfolios. Because the results in Panel A Show that firm and product assets under management predict alpha, we. perform two-way portfolio sort. First, we divide products into two categories depending on whether the managing firms’ total assets under management are above or below the median. For small firms none of the alphas are significant. For large firnrs all of the employee ownership sorted portfolios have alphas significantly different. from zero, but not significantly different. from the zero employee ownership portfolio. Second, we divided products into two categories depending on whether there product total assets are above or below the median. There are no significant difference in alpha across 1‘If we estimate this relationship using the percentage of the HM firrrr owned by employees or a quadratic specification. instead of indicator variables. the results are not significant. product total asset and employee ownership sorted portfolios. 2.6.2 Portfolio Manager Ownership and Alpha Since portfolio performance ultimately depends upon the portfolios manager’s ac- tions, we examine the relationship between performance and portfolio manager IIM firm ownership. The results in Table 8 Panel A do not show a clear relationship between portfolio manager ownership and performance. The coefficients are insignifi- cant in five of the six specifications. The Fama-MacBeth regression using the forward Carhart alpha. shows a significant negative relationship with portfolio manager own— ership. However, given that the most reasonable ex ante prediction was for a. positive coefficient and only one of six specifications is significant, we interpret these results as failing to shot" a n‘reaningful relationship between alpha and portfolio manager ownership. The portfolio regression results in Table 8 Panel B show a marginally significant positive alpha for products managed by non—owners and no significant result. for the products managed by employee owners. The long-short portfolio alpha is significantly negative. The alpha of the large firm/ zero portfolio manager ownership portfolio is significantly positive. After performing a two way sort by portfolio managt‘tr IIM firm ownersl‘rip and firm total assets under management there are no significant differences in alpha between portfolios. Similz-rrly, after performing a two-way way sort. with prod— uct total assets, there. are no significant. differences in alpha. between portfolios. These results suggest that any significe-rnce between portfolio manager Ill\f firm (ms’nership and alpha is driven by the correlation between portfolio manager IIM firm ownership and firnr and product size. 76 2.7 Employee Ownership and Risk Taking Employee ownership has two effects 011 risk incentives. First, employee owners have a large undiversified stake in their employer, which will create an incentive to reduce. firm risk. Second, employee owners reap all of the gains from risk taking, and have lower termination risk. To examine the tradeoff between these. considerations. we regress portfolio risk measures on employee ownership. We measure portfolio risk with three variables: tracking error, beta, and portfolio standard deviations. We measure tracking error as the standard deviation of the difference between a product’s return and the benclunark return over the 24 months subsequent to measuring ownership. Table 9 Panel A shows the results of regressions of tracking error on employee own- ership. We include controls for firm and product. size as well as a set of indicator variables for the style and market cap of the products holdings. In the first three columns the t—statistics are based on standard errors clustered by product and time. The first. colunm shows the results of regressing tracking error on firm employee ownership. There is a significant positive relationship between firru employee owner- ship and tracking error. The average tracking error of products managed by wholly employee owned firms is higher by 0.1% per month than products offered by firms with no employee ownership. In columns two and t hree. the portfolio managers’ Il.\l firm ownership is included as an independent variable. Portfolio manager ownership is significant. and the coefficient is twice the size of the coefficient. on firm enrployee ownership. These results provide strong support. for the hypothesis that portfolio manager o\\-'nership reduces career concerns sufficiently to affect investment behavior. The last. column of Table 9 Panel A contains results from a panel regression with firm fixed effects. After controlling for firm level fixed effects. the effect of portfolio K1 ‘1 manager IIM firm ownership is smaller, but the statistically significance is much higher. Even within a firm, products managed by employee owners have higher tracking error than products managed by non-owners. This strongly supports the notion that there is a positive relationship between ownership and risk taking. Table 9 Panel B shows the results of regressing betas and portfolio standard de- viations on employee ownership. In the first two columns. the dependent variable is portfolio beta and in the third and fourth columns the dependent variable is portfolio standard deviation. Both are estimated over the 24 months after measuring owner- ship. Firm level employee ownership does not significantly predict betas, but it does have a positive relationship with portfolio standard deviations. The portfolio manager results include firm level fixed effects. and find significant positive coefficient for both betas and portfolio standard deviations. The portfolio manager results include firm level fixed effects. These results strongly suggest that employee ownership is positively associated risk taking. The causal interpretation of these results is that employee ownership reduces career concerns, resulting in greater risk taking. However, there are alternative explanations. The reverse causality explanation is that firms grant ownership as a reward for taking risk. Given that employee ownership rarely changes in our sample this seems unlikely. Another alternative is that both portfolio risk and employee ownership are driven by portfolio managers’ risk aversion. Individuals with low risk aversion are more likely to form their own firms and manage riskier portfolios. 2.8 Conclusion Eriipltiiyee mvnership of HM firms is common. and there is large variaticm in own- ership structures across firms. In this paper. we 1')rovide the first. empirical analysis of 78 IIM firm employee ownership. We View employee ownership as one tool that IIM firms use to control the agency problem between firms and employees, and we argue that in equilibrium firms should be driven to optimal ownership structures by market. com- petition. This implies that employee ownership should. vary cross-sectionally based on firm characteristics measuring the costs and benefits of employee ownership. How— ever, in equilibrium there should not be an observable relationship between employee ownership and performance. We begin our empirical tests by analyzing the determinants of employee ownership at the firm level. Then. we look within firms, and test which portfolio managers have an ownership position in their employer. Our results are broadly consistent with an optimal contracting equilibrium. Employee ownersl‘iip is higher when its value is greater. Within firms. we find that portfolio managers who are also firm executives, who manage multiple products, or who manage a large proportion of their firms’ assets, have significantly higher ownership. Next we test if employee ownersl‘iip predicts performance. We fail to find a con— sistent significant relationship between firm level employee ownership and alpha. We interpret this result as consistent with an e(_1uilibrium in which firms and employees allocate ownership optimally. and clients allocate funds correctly given the observable characteristics of firms and products. Finally, we test if employee ownership is related to risk taking. Vi-"e show that employee owned firms‘ products have significantly higher tracking errors and standard deviations. \IVithin firms. products managed by einpltiiyee owners have significantly higher tracking errors. betas. and standard deviations than products managed by ll(’)11-()\\'Il(—'?I‘S. The portfolio nr-amager results hold even after including firm fixed effects. While there is a. huge body of academic work examining agency conflicts between portfolio management. firms and their clients. the agency problem between portfolio 79 management firms and their employees has received far less attention. This is the first study to examine employee ownership of portfolio management firms as a. means of controlling this agency problem. Overall, our results are consistent with an optimal contracting equilibrium. in which firms and employees efficiently trade off the costs and benefits of employee ownership. 80 2.9 Appendix The firm is defined as the investment adviser or “separately identifiable department or division” (SID) of a bank. Each firm may have. one or multiple products. Firms are matched from the SEC Form ADV data to the PSN dataset using a name match and are verified using a combination of city, state and assets under management. The employee ownership variable captures the amount. of t he investment firm itself (i.e. not the assets under management) that is owned by employees of the firm. Our data source for investment firm ownership is SEC Form ADV. If a firm files multiple times within a month, we retain the latest filing in that month. The form must be filed annually and "other than annually” if Items I (Identifying Information). 3 (Form of Organization), 9 (Custody) or 11 (Disclosure Information) become inaccurate or Items 4 (Successions), 8 (Participation or Interest in Client Transaction) or 10 (Control Persons) become materially inaccurate. Schedule A contains information about direct owners and executive officers. Each CEO, CFO, COO, CLO (Chief Legal Office), CCO (Chief Corntfliance Officer). director must be reported. Each shareholder with a direct ownership of greater than 5%, all general partners, and these limited partners and members that have right to receive upon dissolution or have contributed more than 5% of the capital must report ownership on Schedule A. On Schedule B, all indirect owners that have a. 25% interest in any entity listed in Schedule A are recorded. Using Schedule B we find the true controlling ownership stake of each entity listed in Schedule A. Based on the field “Title or Status“, we define whether each entity is an enmloyee or non-em})loyee. On Schedule A, the ownership is classified into 6 groups: “NA - Less than 5%", “A -5‘% but than “JO/t”. “B 40% but less than 25%", "C 25% but less than 50%", “D 50% but less than 75%", “E—75‘7t1: or more". To construct. a single value for each ownership stake, we apply the following algorithm. 81 We sum the number in each ownership group. Starting at “IS—75% or more”, we build an upper and lower constraint based on the sum of each of the other groups except “El-75% or more” multiplied by the maximum and mininnnn possible value for each of the other groups. We then take the midpoint of the maximum and minimum possible value as the. value for any entity classified as “Ii-75% or more”. We then construct the constraints for “D 50% but less than 75%" again as above using an upper and lower constraint based on the sum of each multiplied by the maximum and minimum possible value for each group except now we omit “D 50% but less than 75%” and use the value for “E-75% or more” as both the minimum and maximum constraint for “E-75% or more”. Again, we take the midpoint of the constraints as the value for “D 50% but less than 75%”. We proceed recursively until we obtain values for each group, finishing with the smallest ownership group. We verify the validity of the results of the algorithm by ensuring that each calculated group value falls within the prescribed range and that the values of all the stakes in a single firm sum to 100%. For the small number that do not, we correct these entries by hand. (E.g. there are % or more” ownership stake is reporting errors where a. single individual with “E—75 listed multiple times for multiple positions: CEO, CCO) We then sum the ownership stake associated with employees. 82 Table 2.1 Summary Statistics Panel A shows summary statistics of employee ownership. Panel B shows summary stat is- tics of firm level variables. Panel C shows summary statistics for portfolio manager level variables. In Panels A through C each observation is included once per year. Panel D shows product level summary statistics with monthly observations. Panel A: Ownership Mean SD 25th% Median 75th% Firms with Employee Ownership 72.6% Avg. Largest Position > 0 56.8% 29.3 32.5 55 82.5 Avg. Top Three Positions > 0 78.2% 28 62.5 92.5 100 Avg. Employee Ownership > 0% 89.5% 23.2 100 100 100 Products with PM Ownership 17.5% Avg. PM Ownership > 0 52.1% 33.3 21.3 50.0 82.5 Panel B: Institutional Investment 1\~’Ianagement Firms Mean SD 25th% Median 75th% Total # of Firms 1,118 ' Avg. # of Firms per period 843 # of Professional Employees 50 176.8 6 13 29 # of Products 5.06 7.54 1 3 5 Other Business Segments 0.19 0.49 0 0 0 Index % 2.4% 12.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 Firm Portfolio Turnover 65.5% 64.5 26.2 46.7 82.7 Style Herfindahl 0.89 0.19 0.87 1 1 Non—Portfolio Services 0.61 0.77 0 0 1 Firm Total Assets $31 17,783 76.110 270 1,222 5.810 Percent Equity 72.8% 37.0 47.7 100.0 100.0 Percent International 4.3% 17.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 Percent Core 32.7% 41.9 0.0 0.1 79.6 Small Cap % 16.8% 31.9 0.0 0.0 14.6 83 Table 2.1 continued Panel C: Portfolio 1\‘Ianagers Mean SD 25th% Median 75th% Total # of PMs 3,118 # Products l\lanaged 1.9 2.1 1 1 2 Key Person 0.18 0.38 0 0 0 Proportion of Products Managed 32.3% 34.8 5.9 16.7 50.0 Proportion of Assets Managed 24.7% 32.9 1.3 7.1 37.8 Tenure 10.5 7.9 5 9 14.7 PM Index 0.0% 6.9% 0.0 0.0 0.0 PM Turnover 53.7% 70.9 3.9 34.0 75.0 PM Style Complement 35.4% 40.6 0.0 14.2 74.8 PM Asset Class Complement 53.9% 39.4 9.0 55.9 99.2 PM Percent Equity 70.2% 44.3 0.0 100.0 100.0 PM Percent Core 22.2% 38.7 0.0 0.0 33.3 PM Percent Small Cap 23.3% 40.9 0.0 0.0 21.7 Panel D: Investment Products Mean SD 25th% Median 75th% Total # of Products 3.605 Product Total Assets $.\I 1.350 3.868 48.6 251.8 1.016 Unadjusted Returns 0.72% 4.56 -1.92 0.96 3.55 One Period Carhart Alphas 0.05% 1.87 -0.86 0.01 0.91 Forward Carhart Alphas 0.04% 0.48 -0.19 0.02 0.27 Russell Alphas 0.24% 2.48 -0.85 0.15 1.25 Trackil’lg Error 1.90 1.22 1.09 1.04 2.50 84 Table 2.2 Summary Statistics by Employee Ownership This table shows pooled averages of the variables used in this paper. Each column shows pooled averages for firms that fall into a specific ownership category. Panel A shows summary statistics for firm level variables. Each firm is observed annually. Panel B contains product level variables. Each product. is observed monthly. Panel A: Institutional Investment Management Firms Zero Minority Maj ority 100% % of Firms in Category 28.8% 5.5 10.9 54.7 # Professional Employees 116.1 23.3 13.6 17.7 # of Products 9.4 4.8 3.2 3.6 Other Business Segments 0.29 0.16 0.20 0.15 Index % 4.8% 6.3 1.6 1.9 Firm Portfolio Tiu'nover 73.0% 70.4 68.6 60.7 Style Herfindahl 0.80 0.87 0.93 0.93 Non—Portfolio Services 0.72 0.52 0.53 0.59 Firm Total Assets $M 55,577 18,254 2,728 4,573 Percent Equity 74.1% 85.4 91.7 83.6 Percent International 13.0% 9.4 8.8 5.3 Percent Core 36.1% 34.2 32.8 30.2 Small Cap % 15.6% 21.7 26.6 19.7 Panel B: Products Zero Minority Majority 10(_)% Product Total Assets SM 1,914 936 810 898 Unadjusted Returns 0.74% 0.65 0.82 0.70 One Period Carhart Alphas 0.04% 0.06 -0.01 0.06 Forward Carhart Alphas 0.06% 0.03 0.01 0.02 Russell Alphas 0.25% 0.28 0.18 0.25 Tracking Error 1.8% 2.1 1.9 2.0 Table 2.3 Summary Statistics by Portfolio Manager Ownership This table shows pooled averages of portfolio and product level variables used in this paper for two ownership categories: products managed by employees with no employee ownership, and products managed by employee owners. Panel A contains summary statistics at the portfolio manager level. Each portfolio manager is observed annually. Panel B contains summary statistics at the product level. Each product is observed monthly. Panel A: Portfolio I\ 0 Key Person 10.40% 55.7 Proportion of Products Managed 24.5% 71.4 Proportion of Assets Managed 11.8% 52.7 Firm Total Assets $3M 107,718 3,030 Tenure 9 .8 13.0 PM Index 0.1% 0.0 PM Turnover 56.1% 43.9 PM Style Complement 0.32 0.51 PM Asset Class Complement 0.52 0.61 PM Percent Equity 68.7% 76.6 PM Percent Core 21.6% 24.9 PM Percent Small Cap 12.8% 14.6 Panel B: Product Level Zero PM Ownership > 0 Product Total Assets $M 1,997 657 Unadjusted Returns 0.64% 0.60 One Period Carhart Alphas 0.11% 0.10 Forward Carhart Alphas 0.12% 0.06 Russell Alphas 0.26% 0.24- Tracking Error 1.90% 2.0 86 Table 2.4 Survival This table shows annual product. survival of firms and products in the PSNT database. Panel A shows summary statistics of firm survival for different. categories of employee ownership. Firms are considered to disappear if they no longer file SEC Form ADV. If a firm continues to file Form ADV but. no longer reports to the SEC it is identified as ceasing to report. Panel B shows summary statistics of product survival for different categories of employee ownership. Panel C shows the result of random effect panel probit regressions where the dependent variable equals one if it is the firm or products’ last period. Constants are included but not reported. The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Firm Survival Summary Zero l\"linority Majority 100% All Survive 96.0% 96.9 96.7 96.7 96.5 Firm Ceases to Exist 2.6% 2.6 2.4 2.0 2.2 Firm Ceases to Report 1.5% 0.5 0.9 1.3 1.3 Panel B: Product. Survival Summary Zero Minority l\iajority 100% All Survive 98.5% 98.2 98.1 98.1 98.2 Product and Firm Disappear 0.7% 0.6 1.1 1.3 1.0 Product Disappears 0.8% 1.2 0.9 0.6 0.7 Panel C: Panel Probit Regressions of Survival Firm Survival Product Survival Firm Ceases Product and Only Product Disappears Reporting Firm Disappear Disappears Employee Ownership % 0.0001 ~0.017 (0.08) (1.63) PM Ownership % -0.003 -0.001 (1.01) (0.07) Ln(Firm Total Assets) 0.10 -0.860 0.159 —0.285 (-0.23) (4.73)*** (6.36)*** (1.06) Ln(Product Total As- -0.293 0.083 sets) (-14.())*** (-0.39) Lagged Alpha. -0.613 0.100 (-8.97)*** (-0.27) # Observations 5.081 5.081 222.721 222.721 Table 2.5 Determinants of Institutional Investment Management Firm Employee Ownership This table shows the results of random effect panel Tobit. regressions where the dependent variable is IIM firm employee ownership. There is one observation per IIM firm per year. In column one, employee ownership is the single largest employee ownership position. In column two, employee ownership is the three largest positions. In column three, employee ownership is the sum of all employee ownership positions. Constants are included but. not reported. The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at. the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Largest Three Largest Total Employee Position Positions Ownership Ln(# Professional Employees) -8.278 -9.602 -12.561 (3.32)*** (5.30)*** (4.48)*** Ln(# of Products) -5.722 -8.468 0.957 (3.11)*** (4.43)*** (0.39) Other Business Segments 4.923 0.101 -3.041 (2.11)** (0.04) (0.73) Index % —12.046 -44.420 -23.672 (2.36)** (6.25)*** (2.11)** Firm Portfolio Turnover -0.061 -0.018 -0.006 (4.01)*** (1.13) (0.23) Style Herfindahl —5.516 14.228 -1.378 (1.08) (2.00)** (0.16) Non—Portfolio Services -1.223 -1.622 3.618 (0.29) (1.20) (1.77)* Ln(Firm Total Assets) -7.090 -7.675 -4.464 (9.24)*** (7.89)*** (3.03)*** Equity % -2.140 0.883 24.005 (0.39) (0.20) (3.33)*** Percmit International 1.734 2.726 -5.454 (0.35) (0.57) (0.79) Percent Core -12.191 -9.053 -27.77' (2.88)*** (3.48)*** (7.42)*** Percent Small Cap 3.053 3.064 —3.947 (0.74) (0.94) (0.90) Pseudo R2 0249 0.300 0.231 Number of Observations 2.609 2.609 2.609 Table 2.6 Determinants of Portfolio Managers’ Ownership of Institutional Investment Management Firms This table shows the results of regressions where the dependent. variable is portfolio manager ownership of their IIM firm. There is one observation per portfolio manager per year. In the first column, the coefficients are estimated using a random effects panel Tobit model. In the second column, the results are estimated using a panel regression with firm level fixed effects. Constants are included but not reported. The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Random Effects Firm Fixed Effects Tobit Regression Key Person 16.150 6.516 (17.54)*** (17.76)*** Proportion of Products IVIanaged 40.131 7.052 (23.06)*** (6.80)*** Proportion of Assets IVIanaged 4.679 7.855 (3.42)*** (12.99)*** Ln(Firm Total Assets) -6.752 -0.075 (25.40)*** (0.26) Tenure 0.612 0.157 (11.98)*** (8.87)*** PM Index -18.053 1.111 (2.86)*** (0.60) PM Portfolio Turnover -0.017 0.000 (2.52)** (0.06) PM Style Complement 10.551 1.992 (7.66)*** (4.31)*** PM Asset Class Complement. 7.405 -2.193 (4.51)*** (4.34)*** PM Equity % —8.279 0.413 (5.58)*** (1.13) PM Percent Core. 0.561 0.229 (0.49) (0.64) PM Percent Small Cap 6.070 0.283 (4.54)*** (0.78) Firm Fixed Effects No Yes Time Effects Yes Yes (Pseudo) R2 0.356 0.359 Number of Observations 11.283 11,283 89 week: 332 3:2: $22 332 £19.: 2555530 a 3.: 3o :53. 25s 33 33.3 a: :34: is: :13: E: 8.0.: is: 55. was- macs- was- :93. so? 2%»... 33. 335253 3.80.: E»: 1:24: 38.: .28.: 3.3:: an; :8 So: as: 23.0 53 Eta”: 3% 25:3 is: ism: E»: as: 3.8:: 2:: god. 32. was. ago 30.0 25s were: 3:25: 33:3 3.: 5...: 13.63.: :53 95.3 25.3 meg- $3.0- once- 83.- mass. so: Ego a....,.3_._:sm £2.52 3.3.: E: so: .95.: 1.3:: :3: 5.2. secs 89o ES :50 :3 Base 3,35: 4.2.2252. ::E< £334 £83.50 S334 £53.80 £33. £334 fic:.§0 27:44 8.23.30 :ommflm Uomponm 0C0 Uhdggorm :Qmmzm UOCOQ 0C0 VEBKWA flames/7:820 US$300 m:c_m.r.w:mmm 6R5 SHE “< 350 €3.89: .00: :5 c.3533 Be. 3552.50 .3815 60.50.9553: 2: :0 5:3,: :32: 3,5950% 23 #8:: 52:9: vm 58: 23 .815 £238 :88 259503.: 9535:: of :euBfiE 0.598%: 2: 3: 8:3: :wmmsm 2:32 583 :23: E83: 8:5 3:252 553 wemmfl 00 835.5 of 2:5,: 5:2: Eats... 05 E 550: $30.: 35:3 oi we US$598 Be. 927:: fimieU :28: 0:0 52:20:30 :0 30:85.32: 2: “0:530:30 :28: 23:2: am of $.20 #35:: Cam: €84.30 mi “36: Max:538 2w mange. 9:350 thrash .5353 "5:: 2:3 3 $335.23 $5.53 2353?. 2:? 305.6%»: @200: 05:: £:2£2w3 naemowgeafim “£5389: 0.5 wEm: 8:855? $8 o>> €2.50 8.3350 >535» ...$Eo.€2 .3225: ”832.23 “386:: 5:5 9:20:30 883:8 358:: £5 423?. mbuswoa #56362: 2. 32:21..» 8:25:33: 2: 8.53.5 33mm: 23 we: < Essa .QEmS:Bo mohOEEo :56 2: :0 SEE: 038:8: @3823: we $33: 2: P52? 23:... mEH. @334 9:: 3:98:30 oohofimam EN 23:8 90 5:: :0: 8:: :3: 01:: HOG: OH: mac dyad H3: fi~_n:< :AZCEU 00:73:0w sag; :2: an: 3:: at: 0.: m:.:. ::.: ::.: ::.: m5: 234. ....§_._:0 2:55 :35: 39.3 :Acmdv £393 .13ch Ammav 3.: :0: 0.: :0: 3.: 2:2 002.30 :2: 0:3 3...: 2.0:: Gm: $2: :0: 3:- 3.: E: 8.: 5.: 2:2. 22.2.0 5:: :3: 1 30:: 3:: 3:: $0: 3:: 9 8:- S: E: 0:: ::.: 2:2 0.22.2.0 _:.:0:m-m:04 00:30 >225) ..mtSQZ 3:254 0:0N sexton 30:00:30 0::m0m 00:.5m 0:009:03 “m 3:.an ... . .. . .. . . 0f. . x D .. - . .. .. .... .-. _ . _ 30.50300: $0.7; :5: 1:: :.\:m .32 0f :0 00:00ch? 00:00 .13.. 1:0 in * £0€F§ BEL £03003 ..£:E 35.75.50 00.0150 00: :02: 0:: 303003 ESE 00:30 00.5350 >203? w:0_ 0:02:03 0 :0 0:3: 05 0.50:7. i.:.;m-u:04: _:::_:0 0:5. ...»..3>500000: 0E0. 3:003 :0 ::c :02005 0:: 0: 02:00: 00: .2030. 0:0 .090: .3300: 0:02:03 00:5: 03:0: 2: 5 9:08:30 00...».0350 “0:30 2: .0 £0.00 0:: :0 00:28 00:93:03 mix: 0:20:0Q0: 0:00:00 :5: x33? 2...: m 3:0,: 00:55:00 EN 0309 mnmroi $1.062 wovfio mono: mvoom: $3.9. 22.55.9830 kw :oo Hoo moo moooo Hoooo ooo.o mm 3:: :30 12.: 2a.: :3: 5.3 ooo.o omfio Hmoo owmo wmoo ooo.o 0:32:00 ***C:o.mv *Lmfimv *umeoov *Lhoév 87C ***Awm:3 mmoo- mmoo- vmoo- foo- ooo.o- goo- Amuumm< :50: 92:00:32: :58 :2: 13:3 :58 :33 "33:: :oo ooo.o o._o.o ooo.o ooo.o o:o.o $324 :39: :Ziri :59 :29 $an :58 :33 363 ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o ooo.o- “N. 9:20:30 :5 23:: . .232 fimfiao 232 ”22:50 232 232 22:50 232 $2220 :0mm:m :03?» 0:0 $835,: :023: :020& 0:0 $33.5": :EmmeO m:0:mm0:m0m 70.22: 9250?: ”d. :25: :Emuag.2::m 30:85:20: £3.20: XL :25 0.0m. xxx: 2: a: 00::0:::m:m 30:0: 32 1:: J. 20:25? 27: .303003 ESE QEmbiao 09:01:25 0.5x 0.5:? :25 m_:_0~.;.0.,.0.:: 3.20:: :02r50 00.3350 2.20:3 WE: A.0::A0L::,~A,02: d. :0 :25.q 6:: .0w.::, fizzflt ** 27:: 23 250:0 :fi0:m-m:0:: 5:300 27o 59:95:20: 02m 02:00.5 :0 :5: 35:02: 2:: 0,: 0.25.30: 0.8. . 0:03:02: wofiom 03:0: 0:: :: .QEEQESO 0020350 .Swm:2: 0:09.95: :0 20:: 2: :0 “00:200. 20:02.5: 9:»: 2057.05,: 05:20 :5: 22:3: 20: m 3:45: 20:5 :EE:0:0: 0:0 :0 2:30: :02: 2.30800w 0:: 6:: 23:2: vm 38: 0:0 :25 2:30.: :22: 2.52:00w 35300:: 2:: :0230: 00:08::0 0:: 0.5 20:90. :0nm:m £530: 588 @030: 28.550 22:3 @523: :32: vuwws: :0 5300.3 2: 2:5: 5:9: 28.50 2: E 550.: 3:00: mnwa: 2: 0: @03835 0.5 20:30 022250 :25: 0:0 @3225»: :0 2:222:32: 2: 295020: @020: 5:08 wm 23 :25 3:9: fiooi ta:$0 0:0 mam: #0322520 0:». 22:3: 93:20 02.05.20,: .5508: :5: 2:3 2: @8323 20:0 @328? 5:: 25600ng @200: :5: .2563:me :Emumz-2::m “$0052: 03.: mix: 02:3:2w5 .73 03 :i: 2: :2: 5 9:20:30 “mSwfiHE: 0:038: 2 .05 9:20:30 2n: 6:3: M33005 12:03:05 .2 032.3». 9201:0901 2: 0:2,?» 3:50.: 2: 0:: < 35$ d322§0 .Swm:w:~ 0:398: :0 22:3: 0:80.20: $5223.: :0 £170.: 2: 1.30:1. .033 2:: 2:34 6:: 3:20:30 :mwwgmz ozotuom wd 03:8 an: $9.3 :630 r5.0. 00.0 2.0 5:34. 0.20.30 0,935.5 3.0.34 3:: 89.3 3...: 00.0- 00.0 #00 337$ €20.26 Sizzm 2.32m 20.3 850v #32098 3.0 :20 2.0 .5002 0,542.0 EEK 93...; ans $58 E: N00- 30 00.0 37:4. ,0.:.:_.:U :ZE :E:m .3253 See 1%.: 000. N00 0H.0 37:4. £22030 ...:im-w:aq 0:15:30 2m GEN A..::.t.5m 5:33:33 £15.30 035m 233.5% ”m 355 032328 0N @319 93 Table 2.9 Employee Ownership and Tracking Error, Betas, and Standard Deviations Panel A shows the results of regressing the next 24 months’ tracking error on employee ownership. The first three columns show pooled regressions with standard errors clustered by product and time. The last column is a panel regression with firm fixed effects. Panel B shows the result of regressing the next 24 months’ betas and portfolio standard deviations on employee ownership. For both variables, the first column contains results from pooled regressions with standard errors clustered by product and time, and the second column contains results from panel regressions with firm level fixed effects. The symbols *, ** and “* denote significance at the 10%, 5'70 and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Tracking Error Employee Ownership ‘70 0.0010 0.0010 (3.16)*** (2.38)** PM Ownership ‘70 0.002 0.002 0.001 (1.96)** (2.68)*** (4.03)*** Ln(Firm Total Assets) -0.041 -0.035 -0.044 0.012 (4.19)** (3.35)*** (4.27)*** (1.16) Ln(Product Total Assets) -0.074 —0.074 -0.073 —0.082 (7.21)** (7.24)*** (7.14)*** (50.91)*** Style and Market Cap Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Firm Fixed Effects No Yes No Yes Time Effects No Yes No Yes Constant 2.274 2.210 2.323 2.534 (20.88)*** (19.17)*** (20.36)*** (26.88)*** R2 0.10 0.10 0.10 0.19 # Observations 97.540 97.540 97,540 97.540 94 Table 2.9 continued Panel B: Betas and Standard Deviations Portfolio Betas Portfolio Std. Deviations Employee Ownership (7C 0.0001 (0.70) PM Ownership % Ln(Firm Total Assets) 0.003 (1.71)* Ln(Product Total Assets) 0.007 (3.48)*** Style and l\-‘Iarket Cap Ef- Yes fects Firm Fixed Effects No Time Effects No Constant 0.816 (39.61)*** R2 0.07 # Observations 97.540 0.0002 (2.47)** 0.020 (7.52)*** 0.010 (23.95)*** Yes Yes Yes 0.654 (27.43)*** 0.05 97,540 0.001 (1.09)** 0.013 (1.45) -0020 (100* Yes No No 3.477 (25.51)*** 0.18 97.540 0.002 (7.71)*** 0.087 (7.64)*** 0.001 (0.51) Yes Yes Yes 4.149 (40.82)*** 0.58 97.540 Chapter 3 Fraud and Registered Investment Advisers The recent publicized cases of fraud by investment advisers has bought much at- tention to fraud detection. On December 11, 2008, the Securities and Exchange Com- mission (SEC) charged Bernard “Bernie” Madoff and his investment firm. Bernard L. Madoff Invest incnt. Securities LLC, with securities fraud for a multi-hillion dollar Ponzi 1 scheme that he pe.r1_)etrated on advisory clients of his firm. Estimates of client. losses (included fal'n‘icated gains) amounted to nearly $65 billion.2 Only two month later, on February 17. 2009, the SEC charged Robert Allen Stanford and three of his compa- nies for orchestrating a fi‘z-i.uc.lulmit., multi-billion dollar investment. scheme.3 Given the massive task of overseeing over ten thousand individual investment. advisers. federal regulators could benefit by knowing which firm attrilmtes, such as potential conflicts of interest, make firms more likely to commit fraudulent actions. The SEC tries to examine advisers with a high risk profile on a three-year cvcle and has no set cycles 1http://w\vw.sec.g()v/news/press/2008/20t18—293.]itin 2Amir Efrati and Robert Frank “Madoff Set to Plead Gnillv to 11 Felonies “a“ Street Journal. “’ednesdav. March 11. “2009 '3http://www.sec.gov/news/press/2()09/2t109-26. ht m 96 for others. A better prediction model would also benefit regulators by quantifying the potential for trouble. The inx-estment advisers in the. U.S. provide advice to over 20 million clients and have discretionary control of over $32 trillion in assets. Despite this large sum, reg- istered investment advisers (RIAs) have very few restrictions imposed by federal law. Instead, the SEC relies on mandatory disclose of potential conflict of interests. so that clients can make an informed decision. The recent incidences of fraud by investment advisers raise the question of whether these disclosures are valuable. Using these mandatory disclosures by investment advisers, we are able to predict which firms have future incidences of fraud and other investment—related crime. We find that. conflicts of interest are associated with an increased level of fraud. Internal monitoring and aligned incentives lead to 1(_)wer frequency of fraud. The presence of sophisticated clients is negatively related to the frequency of fraud. Even after accounting for all the above factors, a history of disciplinary actions against the firm predicts fraud. Overall, the required disclosure is useful for predicting fraud, and the probability of events is positively correlated with permissive firm policies and negatively correlated with internal and external monitoring. The ability to avoid losses resulting from inadequate or failed internal processes, people and systems is important for investors using advisers in the United States. The primary federal law that regulates investment advisers is Investment Advisers Act of 1940. Unlike many countries, in the United States, the federal securities laws do not mandate a minimum level of experience, specific qualifications, or accreditations. The laws also do not prohibit advisers from having substantial conflicts of interest. that. could impact their objectivity. Instead. federal law only outlines the disclosures that advisers must. provide and leaves the responsibility for selecting the advisers to investors. 97 we also examine investors reaction to events. Investors appear to only withdraw funds from the firm when the offense is by investment adviser firm owner. A rational manager will fire an employee only when the costs of retaining the employee exceed the benefits. If the employee is also an owner, it may be more difficult to terminate the employee. Consistent with this view, we find that key persons that commit fraud or other crimes are fired more often when they are not an owner. The biggest contribution of this paper is to show that the disclosure mandated by the SEC is useful in predicting future events, even if we cannot say with certainty that this is economically efficient since we do not observe the cost of disclosure or expected losses from operational events. Our work contributes to the larger literature of prediction of fraud and operational events in other financial companies such as in hedge funds: Liang (2003), Bollen and Pool (2008), Brown, Goetzmann, Liang, and Schwarz (2008), banks: Chernobai, Jorion, and Yu (2009), and mutual funds: Cici, Gibson, and Moussawi (2006) and Nobel, Wang, and Zheng (2006). Our work also contributes to the literature on firm and market reaction after a scandal in mutual funds: VVellman and Houge (2005), Choi and Kahan (2007) and public companies: Agrawal, Jaffe, and Karpoff (1999), Karpoff and'Lott, Jr. (1993), Karpoff, Lee, and Martin (2008), Fich and Shivdasani (2007), N iehaus and Roth (1999), and Srinivasan (2005) 3.1 Registered investment advisers (RIAs) An investment adviser receives compensation for providing advice about individual securities or managing portfolio of securities for clients. The Investment Advisers Act of 1940 requires any investment. adviser that manages $25 million or more in client assets to register with the SEC. while those with less assets under management must. 98 register with the state of their principal place of business. The Office of Investment Adviser/ Investment Company Examinations reports the existence of over 10.600 IAs 4 with total assets of $32.3 trillion dollars and nearly 20 million clients. Common examples of investment advisers include pension fund managers, mutual fund families, and trust fund managers. Individuals, partnerships, or certain corpora- . I" tions may also be reglstered under the Act.‘) W'hile passed at a similar time as the Investment Company Act. of 1940, the Invest.- ment Advisers Act of 1940 covers a. related but broader set of investment firms. For example, the investment adviser, Fidelity Management and Research Company (cov- ered by the Investment Advisers Act of 1940), advises the Fidelity family of mutual funds (covered by the Investment Company Act of 1940). Section 203(1))(3) of the Advisers Act exempts from registration investment ad- visers that during the preceding 12 months have had fewer than 15 clients, do not advise an investment company registered under the Investment Company Act of 1940, as amended, nor “hold thmnselves out to the public." as investment advisers. Many hedge funds use this exemption to avoid registration. A rule passed by the SEC re- quired hedge fund managers to register by F eln'uary 1, 2006, but this rule was reversed by the U.S. Court of Appeals for the District of Columbiz—r on June 23, 2006. Further- more. an investment adviser can be part of a firm that serves many different types of 4These values are repm'ted as of October 2nd. 2007. Source: http://www.sec.gov/about/ offices/ocie/ocie_offices.shtml '5 The definition in the Investn‘icnt Advisers Act of 1940 includes any person or business who, for compensation. engages in the business of advising others. either directly or through publications or writings. as to the value of securities or as to the advisability of investing in. purchasing. or selling securities. or who, for compensation and as part of a regular business. issues reports concerning securities. The definition also explicitly exempts banks; a lawyer, accountant, engineer, or teacher whose performance of such services is solely incidental to the. practice of his profession: any broker or dealer whose performance of such services is solely incidental to the conduct of his business as a. broker or dealer: and a publisher of any bona fide newspaper. news magazine or business or financial publication. A “two year lockup" provision is included so that venture capital and private equity firms are. excluded from registering as an RIA. 99 clients or conducts other lines of business such as insurance or banking. A firm that qualifies under the Investment Adviser Act of 1940 must. register even if investment. advice is not its primary business. With the variety of business models and ways to generate revenue, potential con- fiicts of interest may arise within the RIA firm. In addition to managing portfolios for clients, RIAs may provide a broader range of financial planning services such as insurance, tax, and estate-planning. Other RIAs may provide pension consulting, se- lection of other advisers, publication of newsletters, security rating, and market timing services. The investment adviser may be part of a firm that also engages in business as a broker-dealer, insurance broker, and/ or bank. In these cases, an opportunity for self-dealing may arise. By law an investment. adviser is considered to be acting in a fiduciary capacity on behalf of clients with a. higher standard of disclosure and due care, a commitment to disclose, minimize and resolve conflicts of interest than would be found in a traditional securities brokerage environment. Registration also requires that firms adopt a code of ethics. 3.1.1 Conflicts While an RIA has fiduciary duty to investors, a number of potential conflicts of interest. can arise depending on the way the RIA is structured. The conflicts can be mitigated by external monitoring by clients who can leave the firm if they disapprove of firm behavior. Internal governance mechanisms can align incentives and make fraud less attractive. The. presence of a. conflict is not necessarily a bad thing; likewise, more internal governance is not always better. In equilibrium. the added cost due to the potential for wrong doing owing to a particular business practice must be balanced out by the benefits of that practice in a competitive industry. Of course, there is no guaramtee that drew is an equililjirium relationship in the investment adviser industry. 100 For example, the practice of soft dollar brokerage has offsetting costs and benefits. In the advisory business, a common practice is to direct client trades to a particular brokerage that may have a higher commission than other brokerages in return for credits that. can used for proprietary research or other benefits. Since RIAs have a fiduciary obligation to their clients. those. RIAs that engage. in this practice argue. that the extra commissions that they pay are fairly compensated through the research and other products they receive. However. the lack of transparency makes this hard to observe. Bogle (2009) argues that this practice should be discontinued as the lack of transparency and accountability subjects clients to abuse by unscrupulous advisers. Others such as Horan and .lolmsen (2008) defend the practice. They find that premium commissions are related positively to risk adjusted performance suggesting soft dollar usage benefits investors. Overall, while the question of whether soft dollars arrangements benefit clients is still an open one, we predict a positive relationship with the likelihood of a fraud event. RIAs can recommend securities in which they have an ownership interest, serve as an underwriter. or have. any other sales interest. This creates a potential conflict of interest between the firms’ and the clients’ interests. \Vhile the partiality of the firm may be questioned in these cases, refusing to advise to clients about these securities would harm investors by limiting their investment. opportunity set. RIAs may retain custody of clients’ assets or choose to use an outside service agent. Keeping custody in-house allows a one-stop shop that produces all the documentation and holds the money to control costs and provide fast access to assets. However, the arrangement removes any tl'iird-party checks. In her t.esti1non\-' before the Senate Committee. on Banking, Housing And Urban Affairs on Ii/2T/2tlflfl. SEC Chairman Mary Schapiro suggested that the Madoff fraud Would likely have. been discovered sooner if stricter rules had been in effect governing instances in which RIAs take 101 custody of client assets. Likewise, a tight affiliation with a. broker/dealer can open up similar issues. While cost-savings and expediency of service may be gained by in-house broker-dealer ar- rangements, the lack of outside verification can permit fraud to go undiscovered for longer periods of time. Affiliations with other financial businesses can also increase potential conflicts of interest and create opportunities for fraud. Overall, we predict that the use of practices that introduce conflicts of interest. or avoid third-party monitoring (such as interest. in client transactions, soft dollars, internal custody of assets, close affiliation with a broker/ dealer and other affiliations) will open up the firm to a. higher likelihood of a. fraud event. External monitors are a potential solution to mitigate operational risk. Sophisti- cated, powerful investors may be better able to demand relevant information and spot trouble than less sophisticated investors. Unsophisticated clients may underestimate the amount of operational risk that a firnr permits. Alternatively, smaller clients may not have the market power to demand the disclosures that would allow the client to precisely determine operational risk. The RIA firm may also use internal controls to mitigate operational risk within the firm. By having a high level of employee ownership, the individual employees are more closely tied to the firm, so that reputational penalties may be more effective. The bonding of employee ownership works in two ways. By tightly tying the employee to the firm, ownership increases the employees share of the negative effects the firnr incurs due. to fraud and reduces the profitalnlity of the fraud. Likewise with non- employee owners. the effect of fraud can be mitigated by promptly firing the employee. Also, compensation that is tied to performance can help mitigate. wasteful practict-ws like frivolous use of soft dollars since the managers coinpensation is tightly tied to the client’s performance. In addition to aligning incentives of employees with both the 1 02 firm and clients. the firm can put in place a more stringent internal compliance system, such as separating the role of chief compliance officer.6 This may allow the firm to catch potential problems early on and then fix them. Of course, since the disclosed data only contains events that the SEC discovers, a better compliance department may actual increase the probability that fraud is discovered. 3.2 Operational risk The Basel Committee defines operational risk as: “The risk of loss resulting from inadeqtu—rte or failed internal processes, people and systems or from external events.” In this paper, we use a similar definition focusing on the risk caused by employees and affiliates of the firm, but. excluding operational risks from external events such as terrorism or natural disasters. In their paper on operational risk in the hedge fund industry, Brown, Goetzmann. Liang. and Schwarz (2008) construct a measure of operational risk, the w score, by canonical analysis using the hedge fund (late-il'x-rse, TASS, and disclosures from Form ADV. They find no relation between hedge fund investors fund flows and the. a; score. Brown, Goetzmann, Liang. and Schwarz (2008) also report firm factors like high lever- age and concentrated ownership are associated with a past history of events. In the banking industry, Chernobai, Jorion, and Yu (2009) find that operational losses are related to firm factors such as firm size, volatility. increasing leverage, the number of employees, and profitability as well as the n1acroeconornic environment. The firms suffering from operational losses also tend to be more complex and have. fewer auditor's on the board. “In the case of Bernard l.. Madoff Investment Securities, LLC, Peter Madoff is listed as both the chief compliance officer and the director of trading. 103 A major caveat in interpreting the literature is that committing a fraudulent act is related to but distinct from being caught committing a fraudulent act. This dis- tinction may be meaningful. Operational risk by definition is impossible to observe. The risk factors can vary according to the internal controls put in place by the firm, external monitoring and incentives of the employees. However, even a low-risk firm may experience an event by chance. The observation of operational losses can also depend on the degree of scrutiny that is placed on the firm. If two firms have equal operational risk, but one firm is monitored more tightly then we are more likely to observe. an operational risk event in that firm even if the true risk is the same. Failure to detect an event early can also impact the magnitude of the loss as was the case in the Madoff Ponzi scheme. Ultimately, a. documented fraud event are a product. of both an actual fraudulent event. and the detection of the event. Regulators may not play an important role if market participants have alternative mechanisms to combat fraud. Chang and Evans (2007) argue that while corporate fraud can impose significant costs if left unchecked, evidence shows market mechanisms discipline much bad behavior. The autlmrs conclude the benefits of criminalization must. be balanced with the reduction of socially efficient. risk taking behavior. In a study of the mutual fund scandals, Choi and Kahan (2007) find market-based penalties for mutual funds provide substantial incentives to adopt an organizational structure that reduces the likelihood of scandals. However, they also observe that. investors do not withdraw their assets after scandals that do not harm the investors (e.g. when fund managers use insider trading to benefit. investors). In their work on market. timing in international funds, Goetzmann, Ivkovic, and Rouwenhorst (2001) find that. very limited exploitation of these opportunities suggesting that either the funds effectively curtail day traders or few investors are aware. of these ormortunities. In addition to discipline from clients, firms may be. disciplined by the providers 104 of capital. The firm may lose value because of operational events through losses to intangible assets such as reputation. Karpoff and Lott, Jr. (1993) and Karpoff, Lee, and Martin (2008) show that the negative effect. for firms that commit criminal fraud comes primarily from the reputational penalty. Only a small fraction (6.5% in the Karpoff and Lott, Jr. (1003) study) is directly due. to legal fees and fines. Even after accounting for changes due to reporting the correct earnings, the majority of the announcement loss in firm value is due to reputational penalties. Market reactions or reputation penalties will only occur if the operational risk event conveys new information about the firm. The occurrence of an operational risk event may cause clients to update their beliefs about the unobservable operational risk. However, an occurrence of an operational risk event does not necessarily mean risk is increased. The firm can also update its beliefs about the operation risk and engage in efforts to lower that risk. In Agrawal, J affe, and Karpoff (1999), the authors find that managerial turnover is higher after a fraud event; however, after controlling for firm characteristics fraud events, they find that these events do not increase the benefits to managerial turnover. All activities that. the investment adviser engages in generate some level of opera- tional risk. For example, the RIA may take legal control of the client’s assets to enable it. to easily manage the funds. However, this control makes it possible for the RIA to steal the funds. If the market is competitive, firms should only engage in activities when benefit more than offsets the cost caused by increased operation risk. The RIA industry is highly competitive for several reasons. The barriers to entry are very low. The cost. to file and set up a. new firm is under $1000, as very little physical capital is needed. The basic service is very fungible: a client can easily remove money and start using a competitor. This feature of the industry creates strong product market competition. Fama and Jensen (1983a) argue that firms with the lowest. cost structure 105 will be ones to survive. Failure to mitigate operational risk subject to the costs of mitigation will result in uncompetitive fees and/or perforn’iance. To survive, RIAs must optimally mitigate operational risk. 3.3 Data To disclose the potential conflicts of interest. presence of external monitors and internal measures, the SEC requires all registered investment advisers to file a Form ADV annually with the SEC.7 This filing must be updated upon material change - including the occurrence of a fraud charge, so that. clients and potential clients have current available information about the RIA.8 We obtain data for our study from the Form ADV filing required for all RIAS for the years 2001 to 2006. All investment advisers with at least $25 million in assets under management are required to file the Form ADV. Our panel data includes all initial filings and amendments, including the filings of now defunct firms. As firms are legally required to file the Form ADV and we have all filings, the dataset. should be (:oml‘n'ehensive and survival bias free. A criminal DRP must be filed if a “person associated with an investment adviser”9 has been charged or convicted of or plead guilty or nolo contendere (“no contest”) in a domestic, foreign, or military court. to a. felony or misdemeanor involving: investments or an investment—related business, or 7This form is available at http://www.adviserinfo.sec.gov/IAPD/Content/Search/iapd_ 0rgSearch.aspx. 8 The form must be filed annually and “other than annually” if Items 1 (Identifying Information). 3 (Form of Organization), 9 (Custody) or 11 (Disclosure Information) become inaccurate or Items 4 (Successions), 8 (Participation or Interest. in Client. Transaction) or 10 (Control Persons) become materially inaccurate. U The Investment. Advisers Act of 1010 defines this term as any partner. officer, or director of such investment adviser (or any person performing similar fin‘ictions), or any person directly or indirectly controlling or controlled by such investment adviser, including any employee of such investment adviser. except that. for persons associated with an investment adviser whose functions are clerical or ministerial. 106 any fraud, false statements, or omissions, wrongful taking of property, bribery, perjury, forgery, counterfeiting, extortion, or a conspiracy to commit. any of these offenses. Amended Form ADV filings can occur as frequently as multiple times in a single day. To create an annual panel data set, we use the current filing as of August Blst of each year.10 All explanatory variables are measured as of August 3lst. We then collect information on disclosure reporting pages (DRPS) filed September lst to August 31st of the next. year. We have 51,397 firm-years representing 13,579 unique RIAs. The number of unique RIAs exceeds the number of active RIAs reported by the OIA because our sample includes defunct firms. Firm-years with at least one DRP filing L are called an ‘event year”, and those without a DRP filing are called a. “clean year”. In Table 3.1, we observe that RIAs come in a wide array of sizes. While the median assets under management (AUM) is $100 Million, the mean AUM is over $2.4 billion. In Table 3.1, Panels B and C show the structure of the industry with many small advisers and a handful of large advisers. Also noticeable is that the number and frequency of reported events is much higher for larger firms. Firm policies are, vary greatly among investment advisers. We examine several of these policies in Table 3.2. Interest. in Client Transaction is a binary variable that takes the value of one if the firm recommends securities in which it has an ownership interest, serves as an underwriter and / or has any other sales interest. Soft Dollars is a binary variable equal to one if the firm receives research, other products or services other than execution from a broker- dealer or a third party in connection with client transactions. Custody of Assets is a binary variable equal to one if the firm retains custody of clients’ cash and/ or securities. Broker/ Dealer is a binary variable that takes the value of one if the firm reports an affiliation with a bri)ker/dealer. Other Affiliation is a binary variable that l“\\'e choose August 31st to maximize the number of annual observations since our data set of ADV filings ends in September of 2006. “"e have DRP filings through ‘2007. 107 takes the value of one if the firm reports an affiliation with an investment company, other investment adviser, bank, insurance company or other financial company. Small Client Focus is a binary variable that takes the value of one if the reported percent of individual (non-high net worth) clients exceeds 50%. Separate chief compliance officer (CCO) is a binary variable that takes the value of one if the person reported on the Schedule A filing has no job title other than CCO. The CCO of a company is the officer primarily responsible for overseeng and managing compliance issues within an organization. Performance-Based compensation is a binary variable that takes the value of one if the. firm reports that it is compensated based on performance. History of Violations is a binary variable equal to one if the firm has to file a DRP for a fraud event during the last 10 years. The history can be removed if the responsible party is no longer affiliated with the firm or more than 10 years has elapsed. In the first column of Table 3.2, we observe that firm policies that may cause a conflict of interest. are common but not ubiquitous. The last variable, History of Violations, is relatively uncommon. This is not surprising since reputation is very important in the industry. The policies are fairly stable over time as shown in column two. Over ninety percent of firms have the same policy in the current. year as they had in the past year. In Table 3.3 Panel A, we examine the difference in firm policies and fraud. We split the sample into firm—years with zero DRP filings (clean firms) and firm-years with one or more DRP filings (fraud firms). 11 Consistent with the view that firms with more potential conflicts of interest will have more operational risk, we observe a positive and significant differences for all four internal conflict variables. For clean firms, less than a third of firms recommend securities to clients in which they have an economic interest. in nearly tln'ee—fourths of fraud firms, the firm engages in this 11To be precise since our data is a panel, a firm may appear in both samples though in different years. 108 practice. Similarly, the use of soft dollars is 16% higher in event years. The difference in internal custody of assets is nearly 40% higher in fraud firms. The presence of other business activities within the firm or affiliations with related firms with these activities also varies significantly between clean and fraud firms. Broker/Dealer and Other Affiliations are found in 80% and 90% of fraud firms. Both values are significantly higher than in clean firms. In clean firms, only 22% of firms have a primarly low-net worth individual client base, while the figure is 43%- of firms for fraud firms. The prescence of a separate chief compliance officer (CCO) is slightly higher in fraud firms. Also, Performance-Based compensation does not meaningfully vary between the two groups. The most dramatic results while only 0.87:. of firms have a prior history of an event for clean firms, 27.5% of firms have a prior history of events for fraud firms. While these are only unconditional averages and should not be interpreted causally, there is a strong connection between permissive internal polices and future events. Similarly, unsophisticated clients are more likely to be present during event years. Interestingly, the relation between a dedicated CCO and event is positive. One expla- nation is that a dedicated CCO may be more likely to find fraud causing more. events. However, the correlation could be spurious is the number of events increases with size of the firm and larger firms are more able to afford a dedicated CCO. In Table 3.3 Panel B. we examine the frequency of events by year. Although there is no strong pattern in the trend, we include year dummies in all subsequent analysis to guard again faulty inference that could be caused by changing in monitoring by regulators over time. 109 3.4 Empirical results 3.4.1 Prediction of fraud ()ur main research goal is to predict which firms will suffer an operation event based on observable firm characteristics. The 1;)urpose is two-fold. First, an accurate prediction model is useful to investors and regulators to identify firms that have fea— tures that are consistent with a higher incidence of operational risk events. Second, we would like to determine a causal relation between firm cl‘iaracteristics and incidences of fraud events. While our research design limits the possibility of reverse causation, we still need to be concerned about the possible endogeneity of our explanatory variable and event variable. We observe the act of getting caught, not the fraud event itself, so in that our explanatory variable are. correlated with the probability of getting caught conditional on committing a fraud the inferences will shift. Still, we can answer an in- teresting question: do certain practices increase the chance of the firm getting caught for fraud. We use. the filing of a criminal disclosure reporting page (DRP) as the operational risk event. Vt’e cmistruct a panel of RIA firm-year observations and then measure the number of DRP filings over the next year. In our main set. of tests, we estimate a probit. model using an indicator that equals one when there is one or more DRP filings over the subsequent year and zero otherwise. We report the results in Table 3.4. In the first column. we include. five variables that indicate. different types of intermil conflicts. \Ye find that having an Interest in Client Transactions. use of Soft. Dollars, Custody of Assets, affiliation with a. Broker/Dealer. and Other Affiliations all have. statistically significmrt positive relations with the incidence of DRP filings. This is consistent with the view that given a. greater latitude to commit fraud. more fraud will be. cormnitted. 110 In all specifications in Table 3.4, we control for the number of employees using a series of dummies related to the range reported on Item 5a of the Form ADV: 1-5, 6—10, 11- 50, 51—250, 251-500, 501-1,000 and More than 1,000. We also control for firm size, firm age and year effects. As expected. the point estimate of the employee effect increases as the number of employees increase, and a F—test of the combined significance. of the. number of employee variables is strongly significant for all specifications. In the second column of Table 3.4, we include two proxies for external monitoring that are measures of the client type of the RIA: a dummy if the primary client type is individual investors12 and average account size. Neither variable is statistically significant in this specification though the point estimates are the predicted signs. In the third specification. we examine three measure of internal monitoring. Em- ployee ownership is derived from the Schedule A and B filings as described in Dirn- mock, Gerken, and Marietta—Westberg (2009). Employee ownership has a strong and significant negative effect as expected. Performance-Based compensation has a nega- tive effect as expected, and a separate CCO is related to a slightly higher incidence of fraud even after controlling for firm size. However. neither of these variables are statistically significant. In the fourth model. we include all explaimtory variables for internal conflict, external monitoring and internal monitoring. While the model still has the same in- terpretation as a predictive model, the interpretation as a causal model shifts since the some of the explanatory variables are determined by the RIA firm, while others are. set by clients and can be considered an outcome of RIA firms' choices. Overall, the results are remarkably similar to the inferences from the prior models. The statis- tical significance remains for all of internal confiict variables except Other Affiliates. ')r _ . . . . . . ..., . . , l'“I‘lns classification excludes high-net worth investors who have over $150,000 In assets invested with the RIA or over $1.5 million in total net worth, as well as institutional investors that aggregate assets from individuals such as mutual and pension funds. 111 Interestingly, the average account size variable is now significant suggesting that after accounting for the potential conflicts and internal firm monitoring, larger clients are associated with a lower incidence of fraud. In the fifth specification, we also add a control for a history of violations. History of \V'iolations is a binary variable that takes the value of one if the firm reports “yes" to any question on Item 11 (Disclosure Information). This variable is strongly significant indicating a prior history of events is a strong predictor of future events. Again, the interpretation of the other variables shifts as their effect is now conditional on having a past ewmt. However, the statistical and economical significance of the other explana- tory variables remains essentially the same. In the sixth specification, we employee. a random effects probit model to control for unobserved firm-specific cliaracteristics to address an omitted variable concern. Even with this specification, we still have qualitatively similar results that are still statistically significant. Overall, the results are consistent with our predictions. When an RIA firm chooses practices that permit greater freedom to engage in fraudulent practice, more fraud is observed. Sophisticated clients invest with firms that have a lower subsequent incidence of fraud. Also, firms that put strong internal monitoring and incentives to mitigate. fraud see lower subsequent rates of fraud. To test the predictive accuracy of our models. I use the Hanssen—Kuipers score as discussed in Granger and Pesaran (2000). The authors show that the Hanssen- Kuipers score can be interpreted as average economic value when the payoff ratio is (onstant over time and equal to the unconditional forecast probability. The score is ' fruc )osifil’c. . . calculated by H A = H + F, where H = . . 1 . , . . 1s the lnt rate ' ' true posz/H'('+julsc positudc '(zlsc nc( (Mice and F 2 f '1 . . is the false—alarm r'rte. Usin ‘ the full )robit qus-e neg/(1t:m9+fruc negative ' ‘ ( g I model from the last column in Table 3.4, the hit rate. is 20.4% and the false-alarm rate is ().2(i"<,~ yielding a Halissen—I\'uipers score of 20.2%. \Vc can reject that this value 112 equals zero at the one—percent level. A score of zero indicates no skill. This method is preferable over an accuracy measure based only on the number correct since such a method is heavily influenced by the most common category and very few firms have events. For example, a naive forecast of that no firm has a event would score yield a Hanssen-Kuipers score of zero, but have a 99.6% accuracy. Also, our full-model has a statistically significantly higher score than a model that. only considers the historical events, which has a Hanssen—Kuiper’s score of 14.8%. Anecdotally, our model also fares well. Using the most recent filing of the Bernard L. Madoff Investment Securities Form ADV available online (dated 01/07/2008), we find that the projected value. operation risk places the firm at the 97th“ percentile of all firms in our sample. The firm’s custody of its clients assets, close association with a broker/dealer and history of violations13 are all factors for the high score. Another firm that has recent media attention is Stanford Capital Management. Like Bernard L. Madoff Investment Securities, Stanford has custody of its clients assets, close association with a broker / dealer and a history of violations14 as well as various interests in client transactions resulting in a 99th percentile score. Given the strong significance of the number of employees and incidence of fraud, 13According to the Investment Adviser Registration Depository (IARD), the firm had two DRPs on file. On 07/06/2005, the NASD alleged the firm failed to display immediately customer limit orders in N asdaq securities in its public quotation. Without admitting or denying the allegations, the firm consented to the described sanctions and to the. entry of findings, was censured and fined $7,000.00. On 02/26/2007, the firm admitted violations of limit order display and limit order protection. VVith- out admitting or denying the allegations, the firm consented to the sanctions. was censured and fined $8,500.00. 14011 04 /'12/ 2007, the firm held customer funds without making required reserve computations and to make deposits into a special reserve bank account for the exclusive benefit of the customers. The findings stated that the firm failed to establish and maintain a supervisory system reasonably designed to achieve compliance with applicable securities laws, regulations and NASD rules in that it. failed to provide each of its branch offices with copies of its written supervisory procedures or an equivalent document regarding the timely processing of customer checks. The findings also stated that the firm conducted a securities business while failing to maintain its required minimum net capital. \Vithout admitting or denying the findings, Stanford Group Company consented to the described sanctions and to the entry of findings, therefore. the firm was censured and fined $20,000. 113 we run two other checks to ensure that our inferences are not due to the differences in the size (number of employees) of firms. First, in Table 3.5, we. again use the same specifications as in Table 3.4 with one change. Instead of including number of employee dummy varialfles, we split the sample into small and large firms, with small defined as less than 50 employees. Overall, the results are ctmsistent with our previous estimates. The differences in the sample levels of the explanatory variable can account for the difference in statistical estimates. For example, all large firms in our sample have at least one affiliated business so we cannot estimate an effect for that variable. For our second robustness check, we account for the fact that. a firm can have multiple DRP filings for different events in a single year by estimating a count. model where the depei’ident variable is the number of DRPs filed in a single year. we use a negative binomial instead of a Poisson model due to overdispersion of DRPs (the variance is greater than the mean - thus Poisson model is inefficient with downward biased standard errors). We also use the same sets of explanatory regressors as in Table 3.4. ‘We report our results in Table 3.6. Again, our point estimates are qual— itatively siniiilar and all of the explanatory variables except for that Broker/ Dealer remains significant in the full specification (5) and Other Affiliates liiecmnes statisti- cally significant... Overall, our robustness tests confirm that our earlier results are not due solely to difference in firm size or clustering of DRP filings in a. single firm. In Table 3.7. we perform a. similar analysis to predict DRP filed for owners of the RIA firm. We find that we get qualitatively similar results, although the statistical significance is diminished for the conflict of interest variables. Employee ownership remains strongly negative even though there is a positive mechanical relationship lgn‘étween employee ownership and an owner DRP filing. 114 3.4.2 Investor Reaction \Vhile prediction of fraud events is clearly important to regulators, do these events matter to investors? One way to answer this question is to look at investors react to these events. Choi and Kahan (2007) find a negative outflow by fund investors in response to the annoimcement of mutual fund timing scandals. Investor reaction also varied by the degree the scandal negatixcly impacted the fund investors. VVellman and Houge (2005) find that. other funds in same family also suffer outflows suggesting that. investors update their beliefs about risk at the firm level. Interestingly, using a sample of hedge funds, Brown. Goetzmann. Liang, and Schwarz (2008) find no relation between their risk measure from Brown. Goetzmann, Liang, and Schwarz (2009) and flows. There results may differ because their sample only contains a single cross-section of ADV data at the end of their sample period and thus can only tell whether a firm has had a reportable incident during the last 10 years, but not the number or timing of the incidents. Also. their sample consists of only hedge funds. They interpret the findings as hedge fund investors either disregard the ADV or already have the disclosed information from other sources. H(.)wever, their data does not allow them to rule out other plausible explanations such as: investors react immediately or the firm could change after events (e.g. altering policies and/or firing employees). Unfortnnately, the required data on the Form ADV is insufficient to back out investor flow information for RlAs. “/0 therefore use data. on portfolio holdings from the required SEC 13F filings. One limitation of this approach is that this restriction changes our sample from all Rl.-'~\s with over $25 million in AUM to those firms that have at least $100 million in eligible securities. However, this reduced sample contains the. majority of firms with a DRP filing. The Spectrum 13F institutional investor holding database includes all long equity positions on securities that trade on an ()Xt‘:liaiigc or NASDAQ. closed-end funds. 115 some equity options, warrants, and some convertible debt, but no information on short positions or derivatives. We match the Spectrum 13F to Investment Adviser Public Disclose (IAPD) data using a name match and verify our matches using asset under management and place of business that is given in both the 13F and ADV Assets” —(Assetsiqt_ 1*Retu'r'nsiqt_1) filin 1‘s. W’e c'rlcul-tted flows using Flow- 2 f“ ( ( b lat A88€3t8i t—I as suggested in Sirri and Tufano (1998). In Table 3.8, we report regressions of flows using the combined data set. Total DRP is the total number of DRPs filed in the year in which flows are calculated. Owner DRP is number of DRPs filed in which the reported person is an owner of the firm. Prior Return is the return for the prior year. Log(Portfolio Value) is the value of the reported assets in the 13F filing. Four style dummies, large-growth, large-value, small— growth, and small-value are calculated as in Bushee (1998). In the first specification, we see a negative, but economically small and statistically insignificant effect of a DRP on firm flows. However, in the secmid specification, we see that. an owner DRP has an ectmomically and statistically significant effect of roughly -30%. This negative effect of owner DRPs is robust. to inclusion of overall firm DRPs, returns, employee, and style dummies. The evidence is consistent. with investors having little reaction to overall DRPs, but only reacting when the event. is associated with a firm owner. One. reason that our results differ from Brown. Goetzmann. Liang, and Schwarz (2008) may be that data limitations force the authors to use a. risk measure based on a ten year aggregate 1119? sure of events. Therefore, they only observe factors that correlate with a. history of events and not the events directly. Another reason is that we study all RIAs. while their study focuses on hedge funds. 116 3.4.3 RIA reaction Prior work on firm reaction to fraud finds mixed evidence on employee retention after a. fraud event generally implying negative job market penalty for being associated with a fraud. Srinivasan (2005) find directors experience significant labor market penalties. Niehaus and Roth (1099) finds CEO turnover around securities class actions lawsuits, and this effect is larger for successful lawsuits. Farber (2005) finds a positive association between fraud detection and subsequent improvements in board quality and audit committee activity. However, Agrawal, .laffe, and Karpoff (1999) find little evidence of turnover of management or senior directors after the revelation of fraud after control for firm char-attteristics. Fich and Shivdasani (2007) also finds that outside directors do not face abnormal turnover after the rmrelation of f and, but subsequently hold less other board seats. In this section, we investigate one possible explanation for the results in the prior section. While a firm can quickly rid itself of DRP filing by firing the offender, a. firm may be less likely to do so if the person is an owner. One limitation is that while we see all firm employee who report. a DRP, we do not all the complete set of employees who never report a DRP. V’Ve do however have information on all key persons of the firm. A key person is an executive officer, director or owner with influence over firm policy. \V'e can use this information to (‘letermine when a key person leaves the firm, but unfortunately we do not know why they leave. This leaves us with a relative small sample of 87 key people. Using the key person data found on Schedule A. we. construct a. sample of all key persons who file a DRP. In Table 3.9 Panel A, we examine the unconditional probability of departure from the firm. The probability of leaving the firm is much higher for non-owners than owners. Also. key persons who file a. DRP are. more likely to leave for both owners and non—owners. However, the increase in likelihood for non- 117 owners is 5.95% versus an increase of only 0.62% for owners. This is consistent with non-owners being more likely to leave the firm after a DRP. In Table 3.9 Panel B, we use a. probit model where the dependent variable is one if the key person leaves the firm (we cannot separate voluntary departure from forced). we find a strong negative effect of ownership on leaving the. firm even if we include year and key person fixed- effects. Since owners are more likely to be retained after a DRP violation, this can explain why investors react more strongly to owner DRPS than non-owner DRPs. 3.5 Conclusion In this paper, we find evidence that the mandatory disclosures required by the SEC of RIA firms are useful in predicting future fraud and other criminal behavior by RIA firm employees. The firms choice of engaging in practices that. produce potential conflicts of interest is related to an increased probability of future fraud events. Con- versely, internal monitoring, incentive alignment, and sophisticated external monitors reduce the probability of fraud. Investors only react strongly to these violations when the offender is a firm owner. We find that owners are less likely to leave the firm after being charged with fraud. Together this suggests that firms can mitigate the impact of fraud events by firing offenders and investors react. accordingly. We leave to future work extending our analysis to other regulatory violations such as regulator," and civil actions. While criminal behavior is clearly important. it is interesting to see if other types of events, such as regulatory or civil actions can be predicted by firm characteristics. Also, it may be interesting to see if the iriarket [)E‘ll'tlC’l])fllltS take these actions as seriously as they do criminal ones. 118 Table 3. 1 Summary This table presents characteristics of the 13,579 registered investment adviser firms that filed Form ADV with the SEC from 2001 to 2006. Panel A contains the size, number of accounts, age, and employee ownership of the firm. Panel B summarizes the disclosure reporting page (DRP) filings by number of employees. Panel C summarizes the disclosure reporting page (DRP) filings by total assets under management. Panel A: Firm Characteristics Mean SD 25th IVIedian 75th Number of firms 13,579 AUM ($Million) 2,841 19,952 38.3 100 453 Accounts 111,669 11,441,819 8 82 292 Average Account Size ($Thousand) 82,212 839,312 324 1,148 20,782 Firm Age (years) 9.05 ' 8.8 2.25 6.15 13.9 Employee Ownership % 66.7% 44.6% 0% 100% 100% Panel B: Rate by Number of Employees Employees DRPS Total Firm-Years DRPs per Year 1-5 31 25.087 0.001 6—10 18 9,671 0.002 11-50 41 11,144 0.004 51-250 44 3,498 0.013 251.500 ' 21 583 0.036 500-1000 13 432 0.030 1000+ 641 564 1.137 All 809 50,979 0.016 Panel C: Rate by Discretionary Assets Under lVIanagement Discretionary AUM DRPS Total Firm-Years DRPs per Year Less than 1M 68 9,872 0.007 1M-101\'I 1 1.684 0.001 10l\»I-10(');\I 31 17.634 0.002 1001\I—1B 74 14.734 0.005 lB-10B 158 5,510 0.029 100B-1008 328 1.659 0.198 1008+ 149 304 0.490 All 809 51.397 0.016 119 Table 3.2 Consistency of RIA practices This table reports the frequency of certain RIA practices over subsequent firm-years. Interest in Client Transactions is a binary variable that equals one if the firm recommend securities in which it has an ownership interest, serves as an underwriter or has any other sales interest. Soft Dollars is a binary variable that equals one the firm receive research, other products, or services other than execution from a broker-dealer or a third party in connection with client securities transactions Custody of Assets is a binary variable that equals one the firm has custody of clients’ cash and/or securities. Performance—Based compensation is a binary variable that equals one if the firm provides compensation based on performance. Broker/ Dealer is a binary variable that equals one if the firm reports an affiliation with a Broker/ Dealer. Other Affiliation is a binary variable that equals one if the firm reports an affiliation with an investment company, other investment adviser, bank, insurance company or other financial company. Small Client Focus is a binary variable that equals one if the reported percent of individual (non-high net worth) clients exceeds 50%. Separate CCO is a binary variable that equals one if the person reported on the Schedule A filing has no job title other than CCO. History of Violations is a binary variable that equals one if the firm reports “yes” to any question on Item 11 (Disclosure Information). Total Same Remove Add Interest in Client Transactions 31.6% 96.2% 1.4% 2.5% Soft Dollars 58.9% 96.0% 1.6% 2.4% Custody of Assets 26.1% 94.4% 1.4% 4.2% Performance-Based compensation 25.5% 97.7% 1.0% 1.9% Broker / Dealer 40.5% 96.9% 2.0% 1.7% Other Affiliation 56.1% 95.9% 1.9% 2.7% Small Client Focus 23.9% 97.1% 1.5% 2.0% Separate CCO 16.0% 91.9% 0.8% 7.9% History of Violations 0.8% 99.7% 0.2% 0.2% 120 Table 3.3 DRP Summary Panel A reports the relative frequency of certain RIA practices depending on whether the firm has a fraud incidence during the year. The frequency of each practice among all firm-years is tabulated in the first column. The frequency of each practice among all firm-years that do not report a DRP is tabulated in the second column. The frequency of each practice among all firm-years that report at least one initial DRP is tabulated in the third column. The difference between the second and third columns is reported in the fourth column. Fisher’s exact test is used to determined statistical significance of the difference. The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Panel B reports the frequency of DRP filings by year. Panel A: Internal policies versus DRP filings Total NO DRP 2 I DRP Difference. Interest in Client Transactions 31.0% 30.9% 74.6% 43.7%?” Soft Dollars 58.2% 58.1% 74.1% 16.0%”* Custody of Assets 25.7% 25.6% 64.6% 39.0%*** Performance—Based compensation 26.6% 26.5% 29.6% 3.1% Broker / Dealer 39. 2% 39.0% 85.7% 46.7%" * Other Affiliation 54.4% 54.3% 92.1% 37.8%..”* Small Client Focus 22.8% 22.7% 42.9% 20.1%*” Separate CCO 14.7% 14.6% 31.2% 16.6%”‘** History of Violations _ 0.8% 0.7% 27.5% 26.8%"” Panel B: Initial DRPS by year 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 Total Initial DR.PS 62 98 202 198 809 Table 3.4 Probit This table shows the results of pooled probit regressions where the dependent variable is a binary variable. that equals one if an initial DRP is filed in a firm-year. # of Employees is set of dunnnies for each range of employees given in Form ADV Item 5: 1—5, 6-10, 11-50, 51-250, 251-500, 501-1,000 and More than 1,000. For brevity, we include but do not report. these dummies are included (omitting 1-5). We include a set of year dummies. Standard errors are clustered by firm in (1)—(5). Random firm effects are included in (6). Constants are included in the model but not reported for brevity. The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%. 5% and 1% levels, respectively. (1) (‘3) (3) (4) (5) (6) Interest in Transactions 0.159“ 0216*" 0.206" 0.220" (2.10) (2.64) (2.52) (2.19) Soft Dollar 0.171“ 0.189“ 0.185“ 0.219" (2.06) (2.15) (2.17) (2.37) Custody 0.147" 0.139“ 0.099 0.143 (1.90) (1.68) (1.19) (1.63) Broker/Dealer 0.280'“ 0.210” 0.203M 0.263" (3.36) (2.20) (2.10) (2.34) Other Affiliates 0.228“ 0.146 0.151 0.170 (2.24) (1.35) (1.41) (1.28) Small Client Focus 0.073 0.070 0.077 0.093 (0.92) (0.81) (0.91) (0.89) Log(Avg. Account Size) -0.025 -0.044** 41.035” -0.034* (1.49) (2.53) (2.09) (1.73) Employee Ownership % -0.426*** -0.310*** —0.291*** -0.316*** (4.66) (2.76) (2.67) (2.71) Separate CCO 0.056 0.030 0.023 0.015 (0.71) (0.39) (0.32) (0.16) Performance-Based -0.041 -0.031 -0.043 -0.041 (0.47) (0.31) (0.46) (0.43) History 0901"“ 0698"” (6.41) (4.71) Log(AU;\l) —0.027* 0.012 -0.020 0.000 -0.006 -0.012 (1.00) (0.00) (1.19) (0.02) (0.20) (0.51) Log(l7irm Age) 0.038 0.025 0.039 0.027 0.024 0.027 (1.26) (0.84) (1.23) (0.80) (0.75) (0.75) Observations 46.349 46.341 44.376 44.370 44.370 44.370 Pseudo R2 0.24s 0.220 0.252 0.275 0.300 122 Table 3.5 Probit by Firm Size This table shows the results of pooled probit regressions where the dependent. variable is a binary variable that equals one if an initial DRP is filed in a firm-year. The first column. Small Firms, includes only RIA firms with 50 or less employees. The second column, Large Firms, includes only RIA firms with greater than 50 employees. Constants are included in the. model but not reported for brevity. Standard errors are clustered by firm. The symbols *, ** and ”* denote significance at the 10%, 5"}; and 1% levels. respectively. Small Firms Large Firms Interest in Client Transactions 0.183” 0.274* (1.96) (1.78) Soft Dollar 0.075 0.357" (0.73) (2.42) Custody 0.116 0.265“ (1.18) (1.99) Broker/Dealer 0269*” 0.146 (2.65) (0.61) Other Affiliates 0.11.1 (1.03) Small Client Focus 0.030 0.090 (0.24) (0.65) Log(Avg. Account Size) -0.005 -0.105"* (0.23) (3.62) Employee Ownership % -0.300** —0.477* (2.50) (1.76) Separate CCO 0.016 0.034 (0.14) (0.31) Performalice-Based 0.085 -0.321” (0.70) (2.17) Log(AUl\I) —0.022 0.051 (0.69) (1.59) Log(I7irm Age) 0.007 0214”“ (0.18) (2.96) Year Dummies YES YES Observations 40.320 3.790 Pseudo H2 0.072 0.154 _H Table 3.6 Negative binomial This table shows the results of negative binomial regressions where the dependent variable is the number of initial DRP filed in a firm-year. Standard errors are clustered by firm. * tit Constants are included in the model but not reported for brevity. The symbols , an( .1 1*!!! denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. (1) <2) <3) (4) (5) Interest in Client Transactions 0.375 0.680” 0.677” (1.41) (2.41) (2.40) Soft Dollar 0.135 0.422 0489* (0.46) (1.42) (1.71) Custody 0.181 0.240 0.099 (0.67) (0.82) (0.35) Broker / Dealer 0646* 0.4.81 0.450 (1.82) (1.19) (1.06) Other Affiliates 1205*" 0686* 0.711* (2.84) (1.71) (1.83) Small Client Focus 0.221 0.314 0.244 (0.81) (1.20) (0.99) Log(Avg. Account Size) —0.020 -0.099* -0.090* (0.37) (1.67) (1.68) Employee Ownership % -1.575*** -1.202*** 1170*" (5.04) (3.05) (3.09) Separate CCO 0.111 -0.026 -0.032 (0.51) (0.13) (0.17) Performance—Based -0.063 0.006 0.065 (0.23) (0.018) (0.20) History 2542*“ (7.35) Log(AUM) 0.001 0.053 -0.030 0.037 0.013 (0.020) (0.85) (0.56) (0.60) (0.23) Log(Firrn Age) 0.097 0.062 0.138 0.106 0.103 (0.93) (0.59) (1.33) (0.98) (0.98) # of Employee Dummies YES YES YES YES YES Year Dummies YES YES YES YES YES Observations 46.349 46.341 44.376 44.370 44.370 124 Table 3.7 Owner Probit This table shows the results of pooled probit regressions where the dependent variable is a binary variable that equals one when an initial DRP is filed for a firm owner in a firm-year. # of Employees is set of dummies for each range of employees given in Item 5: 1-5, 6-10, 11—50, 51—250, 251-500, 501-1,000 and More than 1,000. For brevity, we include but do not report these dummies. We include a set of year dummies. Standard errors are clustered by firm. Constants are included in the model but not reported for brevity. The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at the. 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Interest in Client Transactions 0.015 -0.187 -0.211 (0.097) (1.05) (1.13) Soft Dollar 0.108 0.091 0.100 (0.64) (0.56) (0.64) Custody -0.036 —0.037 —0.054 (0.21) (0.25) (0.35) Broker / Dealer 0.123 0.069 0.066 (0.75) (0.37) (0.34) Other Affiliates -0.085 -0.153 —0.154 (0.52) (0.82) (0.80) Small Client. Focus 0.068 0.087 0.096 (0.41) (0.50) (0.56) Log(Avg. Account Size) 0.024 -0.008 -0.005 (1.16) (0.36) (0.24) Employee Ownership % -0.282 -0.371* -0.341* (1.42) (1.74) (1.74) Separate CCO -0.019 0.007 0.006 (0.10) (0.044) (0.032) Performaiice-Based 0.222 0.311“ 0325* (1.55) (1.75) (1.86) History 0.826M (2.38) Log(AUM) -0.072*** -0.088*** —0.076*’” -0.077*** -0.083*** (3.05) (3.57) (3.67) (4.17) (4.66) Log(Firm Age) 0.010 0.020 0.016 0.015 0.010 (0.16) (0.32) (0.23) (0.23) (0.15) Observations 46.349 46.341 44,376 44.370 44.370 Pseudo 17") 0.0177 0.0157 0.0390 0.0498 0.0635 Ca"! The dependent variable is Florel-‘t = Table 3.8 Flows Assets”—-Asscts,j‘t_1*Rcturnsm 1 . The sam- Assetsi‘t_1 ple is RIA firms with available 13F data. # of Employees is a set of dummies for each range of employees given in Item 5: 1-5, 6—10, 11-50, 51-250, 251-500, 501-1,000 and More than 1,000. Style is a set of dummies for large cap growth, large cap value, small cap value, and small cap growth. For brevity, we simply report YES if these sets of dummies are included. Standard errors are clustered by firm and year. The symbols *** , and *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels. respmtively. (1) (‘2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Total DRP -0.0001 0.001 0.001 0.0003 (0.042) (0.64) (0.65) (0.23) Owner DRP -0.295*** -0.437"* —0.438*“‘ —0.407*** (3.95) (5.56) (5.61) (5.32) Prior Return 0.252 0.253 0.252 0.253 (1.20) (1.20) (1.20) (1.20) Log(Portfolio Value) -0.010* -0.010* -0.010‘ —0.018” (1.66) (1.66) (1.07) (2.53) Constant 0.050 0.050 0.281“M 0281*” 0282"” 0.392‘" (0.67) (0.67) (2.64) (2.63) (2.65) (3.26) #— of Employee Durn— NO NO NO NO NO YES nnes Style Dummies NO NO YES YES YES YES Observations 7,199 7,199 7,199 7,199 7,199 7,190 R2 0.0000 0.0001 0.048 0.048 0.048 0.053 Table 3.9 Key Person Turnover This table shows the likelihood of key persons leaving the firm after a DRP is filed. Panel A shows unconditional averages. Panel B shows the results of probit regressions where the dependent variable is one if the key person leaves the firm and zero otherwise. Owner is a binary variable that equals one if the key person has an ownership stake in the firm. log(Tenure) is the logarithm of the number of days since the person assumed their current title with the firm. In column three, we estimate the model with a job (employee-firm pair) fixed effect. The symbols *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10%. 5% and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Probability of leaving the firm Non-owner Owner Difference N0 DRP 11.91% 2.77% 9.14%”* DRP 17.86% 3.39% 14.47%*** Difference 5.95% 0.62% Panel B: Regression Analysis (1) (2) (3) Owner -0.900M -1.034** 4.066” (2.06) (2.38) (2.21) log(Tenure) «0.020 0.003 0.007 (0.13) (0.020) (0.036) Constant ~0.907"* —0.963*** —0.971*** (2.97) (3.18) (2.93) Year NO YES YES Key Person Fixed Effect NO NO YES Observations 87 87 87 Pseudo R3 0.1020 0.1231 127 BIBLIOGRAPHY 128 Admati, Anat R., and Paul Pfleiderer, 2008, The ”\Vall Street \Valk” and Shareholder Activism: Exit as a Form of Voice, Review of Financial Studies forthcoming. Agrawal, Anup, Jeffrey Jaffe, and Jonathan Karpoff, 1999, Management turnover and governance changes following the revelation of fraud. J oarnal of Law and Economics 42, 309-342. Almazan, Andres, Keith C. Brown, Murray Carlson, and David A. Chapman. 2004, Why Constrain Your Mutual Fund l\AIanager?. Journal of Financial Economics 73, 289-321. Amihud, Yakov, 2002. Illiquidity and stock returns: Cross-Section and time efffects, Journal of Financial Markets 5, 31—56. Bergstresser, Daniel B., and Thomas Philippon, 2006, CEO Incentives and Earnings Managen'ient, Journal of Financial Economics 80, 511—529. Berk, Jonathan B., and Richard C. Green, 2004, I\‘Iutual Fund Flows and Performance in Rational Markets, Journal of Political Economy 112, 1269—1295. Berzins, Janis, and Charles A. Trzcinka, 2005. Performance and Survival of Institu- tional l\«'loney Managers, W’orking Paper, Indiana University. Bethel, Jennifer, Julia Porter Liebeskind, and Tim Opler, 1998, Block Share Purchases and Corporate Performance, The Journal of Finance 53, 605—634. Bhide, Amar, 1993, The Hidden Costs of Stock Market. Liquidity, Journal of Financial Economics 34, 3151. Black, Bernard S., 1990, Shareholder Pa.ssi\-’ity Reexamined, llIic/zigan Law Review 89,811~892. Bogle, John C., 2009. The End of ”Soft Dollars" 1’. Financial Analysts Journal 65, 48 53. Bollen, Nicolas PB, and V ironika K. Pool, 2008, Conditional Return Smoothing in the Hedge Fund Industry, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 43, 267— 298. Bolton. Patrick. and Ernst-Ludwig von Thadden. 1998, Blocks. Liquidity and Corpo- rate Control, Joarnal of Finance 53, 1-25. Borokhovich, Kenneth A., Kelly R. Brunarski. and Robert Parrino. 2006. Variation in the monitoring incentives of outside blockholders. Journal of La w and Economics 49. 651-680. 129 Brav, Alon, Wei Jiang, Frank Partnoy, and Randall Thomas, 2008, Hedge Fund Ac— tivism, Corporate Governance, and Firm Performance, Journal of Finance 63, 1729— 1776. Brown. Stephen J ., William N. Goetzmann, Bing Liang, and Christopher Schwarz, 2008, Mandatory Disclosure and Operational Risk: Evidence from Hedge Fund Registration, Journal of Finance 63, 2785—2815. Brown, Stephen J ., \Nilliam N. Goetzmann, Bing Liang, and Christopher Schwarz. 2009, Estimating Operational Risk for Hedge Funds: The w-score, Financial Ana- lysts Journal 65, 43—53. Bushee, Brian, 1998, The Influence of Institutional Investors on Myopic R&D Invest- ment Behavior, Accounting Review 73, 305—333. Busse, Jeffrey A., Amit Goya], and Sunil VVahal, 2007, Performance Persistence in Institutional Investment l\lanagement, Working Paper, Emory University. Cadman, Brian D., Sandy Klasa. and Steven R. i\'latsunaga. 2007, Evidence on How CEO Compensation Functions Differ between Execucomp Firms and Non- Execucomp Firms, Working Paper. Carhart, Mark M., 1997, On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance, Journal of Finance 52, 57—82. Chakravarty, Sugato, Robert W'ood. and Robert van Hess, 2004, Decimals and Liq- uidity: A Study of the NYSE, Journal of Financial Research 27, 75—94. Chang. Howard H., and David S. Evans, 2007, The Optimal Prosecution of C(iirporate Fraud: An Error Cost Analysis, \Vorking Paper. Chen. Joseph, Harrison Hong, Ming Huang, and Jeffrey D. Kubik, 2004, Does Fund Size Erode Mutual Fund Performance? The Role of Liquidity and Organization, American Economic Review 94, 1276*1302. Chen. Qi. Itay Goldstein, and Wei Jiang, 2008. Directors Ownership in the U.S. Mutual Fund Industry, Journal of Finance 63, 2629* 2677. Clwrnobai, Anna, Philippe Jorion, and Fan Yu, 2009, The D(_>t.er1ninants of Opera.- tional Risk in U.S. Financial Institutions, Working Paper. Chevalier. Judith. and Glenn Ellison. 1999, Career Concerns of Mutual Fund Man- agers. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 389 432. Choi. Stephen J., and Marcel Kahan. 2007, The Market Penalty for Mutual Fund Scandals, Boston University Law Review 87. 1021 1057. 130 Christopherson, Jon A., Wayne E. Person, and Debra A. Glassman, 1998, Conditioning Manager Alphas on Economic Information: Another Look at the Persistence of Performance, Review of Financial Studies 11, 111—142. Cici, Gjergji, Scott Gibson, and Rabih l\t’Ioussawi, 2006, For Better or W'orse? Mu- tual Funds in Side-by-Side Management Relationships with Hedge Funds, Working Paper. Clifford, Chris, 2008, Value Creation or Destruction? Hedge Funds as Shareholder Activist, Journal of Corporate Finance 14, 3231336. Coggin, T. Daniel, Frank J. Fabozzi, and Shafiqur Ralnnan, 1993, The Investment Performance of U.S. Equity Pension Fund Managers: An Empirical Investigation, Journal of Finance 48, 1039-1055. Conference Board, 2007, Institutional Investment Report: Patterns of Institutional Investment and Control in the United States, New York, NY. Cremers, Martijn, Joost Driessen, Pascal l\*:Iaenhout, and David Weinbaum, 2006, Does Skin in the Game Matter? Director Incentives and Governance in the Mutual Fund Industry, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis , Forthcoming. Cronqvist, Henrik, and Rudiger Fahlenbrach, 2008, Large Shareholders and Corporate Policies, Review of Financial Studies forthcoming. Davis, Gerald E, and E. Han Kim, 2006, Business ties and proxy voting by mutual funds, Journal of Financial Economics 85, 552—570. Del Guercio, Diane, Larry Y. Dann, and M. Megan Partch, 2003, Governance and Boards of Directors in Closed—End Im'estment Companies, Journal of Financial Economics 69, 111~152. Del Guercio, Diane, and Paula A. Tkac, 2002. The Determinants of the Flow of Funds of Managed Portfolios: Mutual Funds vs. Pension Funds, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 37, 523—557. Deli, Daniel N., 2002, Mutual Fund Advisory Contracts: An Empirical Investigation, Journal of Finance 57, 109~133. Demsetz. Harold. 1983, The Structure of Ownership and the 'I‘hem'y of the Firm, Journal of Law and Economics 26, 375 390. Demsetz. Harold. and Kenneth Lehn. 1985a. The Structure of Cbrporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences, Journal of Political Economy 93, 115-5 77. Deinsetz. Harold. and Kenneth Lehn. 1985b. The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences, Journal of Political Economy 93. 1155771177. 131 Dimmock, Stephen G., William C. Gerken, and Jennifer Marietta—Westberg, 2009, Employee Ownership of Institutional Investment Management Firms, Michigan State University Working Paper. Dlugosz, Jennifer, Riidiger Fahlenbrach, Paul Gompers, and Andrew Metrick, 2006, Large blocks of stock: Prevalence, Size, and lV‘Ieasurement, Journal of Corporate Finance 12, 594—618. Edmans, Alex, 2008, Blockholder Trading. Market Efficiency and Managerial Myopia, Journal of Finance forthcoming. Faccio, Mara, and Larry Lang, 2002, The ultimate ownership of Western European corporations, Journal of Financial Economics 65, 365—395. Faleye, Olubunmi, Vikas Mehrotra, and Randall Merck, 2006, When Labor has a Voice in Corporate Governance, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 41, 489—510. Fania, Eugene F., 1980, Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm, Journal of Political Economy 88, 288—307. Fania. Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen, 1983a, Separation of Ownership and Control, Journal of Law and Economics 26, 301—325. Fania, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen, 1983b, Agency Problems and Residual Control, Journal of Law and Economics 26, 327—349. Farber, David B., 2005, Restoring Trust After Fraud: Does Corporate Governance Matter?, The Accounting Review 80, 539— 561. Farnsworth, Heber, and Jonathan Taylor, 2006, Evidence on the Compensation of Portfolio Managers, Journal of Financial Research 29, 305—324. Fee, C. Edward, Charles Hadlock, and Shawn Thomas, 2006, Corporate Equity Own- ership and the Governance of Product l\=Iarket Relationships, Journal of Finance 61, 1217—1252. Fich, Eliezer M ., and Anil Shivdasani, 2007, Financial fraud, director reputation, and shareholder wealth, Journal of Financial Economics 86, 306—336. Furfine, Craig, 2003. Decimalization and market. liquidity. Econmnic Perspectives 27, 1—12. GCI‘V‘dlS, Simon. Anthony W'. Lynch. and David K. Musto, 2005. Fund Families as Delegated Monitors of Money Managers. Review of Financial Stiulics 18. 1139— 1169. Goctzmann, William, Zoran Ivkovic, and K. Geert Rmnvenhorst, 2001, Day Trading International Mutual Funds: Evidence and Policy Solutions, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 36, 287—309. Gompers, Paul A., Joy L. Ishii. and Andrew Metrick, 2003, Corporate Governance and Equity Prices, Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 107 155. Goyenko, Ruslan, Craig W. Holden, and Charles Trzcinka. 2009, Do l\leas1.1res of Liquidity Measure Liquidityl, Journal of Financial Economics 92, 153—181. Granger, Clive, and M. Hashem Pesaran. 2000, Economic and Statistical measures of Forecast Accuracy, Journal of Forecasting 19, 537—560. Hasbrouck, Joel, 2009, Trading costs and returns for US equities: Estimating Effective Costs from Daily Data, Journal of Finance forthcoming. Heflin. Frank, and Kenneth W'. Shaw, 2000, Blockholder Ownership and Market Liq- uidity, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 35, 621-7 633. Himmelberg, Charles P., R. Glenn Hubbard, and Darius Palia, 1999, Understanding the Determinants of Managerial Ownership and the Link between Ownership and Performance, Journal of Financial Economics 53, 353—384. Hirschman, Albert, 1970, Exit. l‘bice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in F irrns, Organizations and States. (Harvard University Press). Holmstrom, Bengt, 1982, l\lanagerial Incentive Problems - A Dynamic Perspective, in Essays in Economics and Management in Honor of Lars ll-‘alzlbeck pp. 210— 235. Swedish School of Economics. Helsinki. Horan, Stephen M., and D. Bruce Johnsen, 2008, Can third-party payments benefit the prinicipal? The case of soft-dollar brokerage, International Review of Law and Economics 28, 56—77. Hu, Henry TC, and Bernard Black, 2006, Empty voting and hidden (morphalfle) ownership: Taxonomy, implications and reforms, Business Lawyer 61, 1011—1070. James. Christopher, and Jason I’x'arceski, 2006, Investor Monitoring and Differences in Mutual Fund Performance, Journal of Banking and Finance 30, 2787—2808. Jensen. Michael C., 1989, Eclipse of the. Public Corporation. Harvard Business Review 67. 617-75. Jensen. Michael C., and \Villiain H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior. agency costs. and mvnership structure, Journal of Firmncial Economics 3, 305 —- 360. 133 . g . 17 I z. *. .. . ‘l - ;’,. ‘7. ..r .. -- . .7. 7.? ’ ‘ M. a n .Y . . - .. 'u.‘ ‘I- :.N- -.-q". ”.9 e: .43‘ 12 .. , - "-"v‘l"l- I u,‘ . u. '.. '5 . '- ...4 I. 3 I t '. ‘1': ‘.J~5. .«f Kalm, Charles, and Andrew Winston, 1998, Ownership Structure. Speculation and Shareholder Intervention, Journal of Finance 53, 99—129. Kang, Jun-Koo, and Jin-Mo Kim, 2006, Foreign Blockholders, Shareholder Rights and Corporate Governance: Evidence from Partial Acquistions of U.S. Firms by Foreign Firms, V’Vorking Paper. Kang, Jun—Koo, and Anil Shivdasani, 1995, Firm performance, corporate governance and top executive turnover in Japan, Journal of Financial Economics 38, 29—58. Karpoff. Jonathan M., D. Scott Lee, and Gerald S. l\*Iartin, 2008, The Cost to Firms of Cooking the Books, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 43, 581—612. Karpoff, Jonathan M., and John R. Lott, Jr., 1993, The Reputational Penalty Firms Bear from Committing Criminal Fraud, Journal of Law and Economics 36, 757—802. Kempf, Alexander, and Stefan Ruenzi, 2008, Tournaments in l\*Iutual—Fund Families, Review of Financial Studies 21, 1013—1036. Khein. April, and Emanuel Zur, 2009, Entrepreneurial Shareholder Activism: Hedge Funds and Other Private Investors, Journal of Finance 64, 187—229. Khorana, Ajay, 1996, Top l\-lanagement Turnover: An Empirical Investigation of Mn— tual Fund Managers, Journal of Financial Economics 40, 403—427. Khorana, Ajay, 2001, Performance Changes following Top l\=’lanagement Turnover: Evidence from Open-End Mutual Funds, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 36, 371—393. Khorana. Ajay, Henri Servaes, and Lei “Ridge, 2007, Portfolio Manager Ownership and Fund Performance, Journal of Financial Economics 85, 179—204. Klu'n'ana. Ajay, Peter Tufano, and Lei W'edge, 2007, Board Structure, Mergers and Shareholder Wealth: A Study of the ;\-alutual Fund Industry, ..lournal of Financial Economics 85, 571—598. Kim. E. Han. and Paige Parker Ouimet, 2008, Employee Capitalism or Corporate Socialism? Broad—Based Employee. Stock Ownership, Working Paper. Korajczyk. Robert A.. and Ronnie Sadka, 2008, Pricing the cmnmonality across alter- native measures of liquidity, Journal of Financial Empirical 87, 45 - 72. Kyle. Albert. and Jean-Luc Vila. 1991. Noise Trading and Takeovers. RAND Journal of Eco'nornic's 22, 54- 71. Lakonishok, Josef. Andrei SlllOlll‘l'. and Robert Vt". Vislmy. 1992. The Structure and Perforim'mce of the Money Management Industry. Brool'ings Paper: illicr'oeconornics pp. 339 391. 134 Lesmond, David A., Joseph P. Ogden, and Charles Trzcinka, 1999, A New Estimate of Transaction Costs, Review of Financial Studies 12, 1113—1141. Liang, Bing, 2003, The accuracy of hedge fund returns. Journal of Portfolio Manage- ment 29, 111—122. Maug, Ernst, 1998, Large Shareholders as l\s’lonitors: Is There a. Trade-Off between Liquidity and Control? , Journal of Finance 53, 65—98. McConnell, John J ., and Henri Servaes, 1990, Additional Evidence on Equity Owner— ship and Corporate Value, Journal of Financial Economics 27, 595—612. Merton, Robert C., 1987, A Simple Model of Capital l\r‘larket Equilibrium with Incom- plete Information, Journal of Finance 42, 483—510. Meschke, J. Felix, 2006, An Empirical Examination of Mutual Fund Boards, Working Paper, University of Minnesota. Mikkelson, Wayne, and Richard S. Ruback, 1985, An Empirical Analysis of the Inter- firm Equity Investment Process, Journal of Financial Economics 14, 523—553. Morck, Randall, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert V ishny, 1988, Management Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 293—315. Morrison, Alan, and William J. \Vilhelm, 2004, Partnership Firms, Reputation, and Human Capital, American Economic Review 94, 1682—1692. Niehaus, Greg, and Greg Roth, 1999, Insider Trading, Equity Issues, and CEO Turnover in Firms Subject to Securities Class Action, Financial Arianagerncnt 28, ['5 52 72. Nohel, Tom, Jay \Vang, and Lu Zheng, 2006, Side-By-Side Management of Hedge Funds and Mutual Funds, Working Paper. Petersen, Mitchell, 2009, Estimating Standard Errors in Finance Panel Data Sets: Comparing Approaches, Review of Financial Studies 22, 432 e480. l’ollet. Joshua M., and Mungo Wilson, 2008. How Does Size Affect Mutual Fund Behavior? , Journal of F inancc , Fortl‘icoming. Pomorski, Lukasz. 2008, Acting on the Most Valuable Informaticm: “Best Idea" Trades of Mutual Fund l\lanagers. \Vorking Paper, University of Toronto. Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert “7 Vishny, 1986., Large Shareholders and Corporate Control. Journal of Political Economy 94, 461 88. 1 35 Sirri, Erik R., and Peter Tufano, 1998, Costly Search and Mutual Fund Flows, Journal of Finance 53, 1589—1622. Smith. Michael P., 1996. Shareholder Activism by Institutional Investors: Evidence from CalPERS, The Journal of Finance 51, 227252. Srinivasan, Suraj, 2005, Consequences of Financial Reporting Failure for Outside Di- rectors: Evidence from Accounting Restatements and Audit Committee Members, Journal of Accounting Research 43, 291—334. Tufano, Peter, and Matthew Sevick, 1997, Board Structure and Fee-Setting in the U.S. Mutual Fund Industry, Journal of Financial Economics 46, 321—355. \Yellrnan, Jay W ., and Todd Houge, 2005, Fallout from the l\Iutual Fund Trading Scandal, Journal of Business Ethics 62, 129-139. 136 M'lllllllllllllllflllllllllllllES