LIBRARY Micluvw. Qm’re yous University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled EMPIRICAL TESTS OF CONTRACT THEORY presented by Meng-Chi Tang has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for the PhD. degree in Economics Major Professor’sTSignature glam/1.7,. atom Date MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Employer - ---nnp.—-._.-._.-.-._.- PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 5/08 K:lProj/Acc&Pres/ClRClDaIeDue Indd EMPIRICAL TESTS OF CONTRACT THEORY By Meng-Chi Tang A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILSOPHY Economics 2009 ABSTRACT EMPIRICAL TESTS OF CONTRACT THEORY By Meng-Chi Tang Contract theory consists of two major parts: the theory of economic institutions and the theory of incentives and information. While most of the related literature focuses on the later part and examines monetary terms, in my dissertation I empirically test the implications from the theory of economic institutions by using information on non- monetary contract terms. Specifically, in the first and second chapter, I extend the current research on the theory of economic institutions by examining the determinants of contract length and contract structures, using the contract information from the National Football League (NFL), the franchising industry, and the coal market. In the third chapter, I empirically test whether contract negotiations vary as a function of an agent’s experience in the NFL. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Five years ago I entered the States for the very first time, 8,000 miles away from home. The loneliness hit me immediately after I woke up in the midnight, in the tiny room of the Owen Hall. It’s the time I realized I am completely alone, and I really missed home. Five years later I am going home, with this dissertation and my degree. It turns out that I was only partially right in my first night here, because I had been getting to know people here since the second day I was here. Some fiiends have taught me things about this profession, and some friends have shared my spare time and personal feelings. Eventually some friends have become both, and this dissertation is dedicated to them. To my advisor, Mike Conlin, who spent a lot of time on this dissertation and also me, I really appreciate your guidance on my way to the academics, and I feel really lucky to meet you. To my dissertation committee members, Thomas Jeitschko and Jay Wilson, thanks for spending a decent time on me and teaching me how to do theoretical works. To my fellow Chinese colleagues, Yi, Wei-Chih, and Jingjing, Professor Davidson told us once that he learned more from his classmates than fiom his teachers, I think I have felt the same way fiom you guys. Not to mention the fun we have during every gathering. To my other fellow students, Wei-Siang, Simon, Nick, J aesoo, Kwang-Myoung, Nichol, Brian, Tom, Ilya. .. thanks for every conversation we have in the class or in the office. This lonely dissertation-writing process became not that boring because of you. I would not be at this stage without my parents’ continuous support. There is no word that can express my appreciation, but I just want to say I am really lucky to be your son. The final words are saved for Pan, who has always been there for me. Thank you. iii TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES .................................................................................... v LIST OF FIGURES ................................................................................. vii INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 1 CHAPTER I CONTRACT LENGTH: EXPECTED SURPLUS, SPECIFIC INVESTMENTS, AND UNCERTAINTY Introduction .................................................................................... 3 Data and Institutional Details ............................................................... 7 Hypotheses ................................................................................. 15 Empirical Strategy ......................................................................... 17 Empirical Results ........................................................................... 20 Conclusion .................................................................................. 27 References ................................................................................... 28 CHAPTER H THE CHOICE OF CONTRACT DURATION AND PRICING PROVISION IN THE COAL MARKETS Introduction ................................................................................. 31 Data and Institutional Details ............................................................. 35 The Choice of Contract Duration ......................................................... 41 The Choice of Pricing Provision ......................................................... 46 The Simultaneous Choice of Contract Duration and Pricing Provision ............ 52 Conclusion .................................................................................. 55 References ................................................................................... 57 CHAPTER HI THE EFFECT OF AN AGENT’ S EXPERIENCE ON NATIONAL FOOTBALL LEAGUE CONTRACT STRUCTURE Introduction ................................................................................. 59 Data and Summary Statistics ............................................................. 62 Empirical Specification and Estimation ................................................. 67 Conclusion .................................................................................. 72 References ................................................................................... 73 Appendix ............................................................................................. 74 iv LIST OF TABLES Table 1 Summary Statistics of the NFL Contracts during 1986-1991 and 2001-2007.. ...................................................................................................... 9 Table 2 Summary Statistics of the Franchise Contracts Information from Bond (2007) .......................................................................... 12 Table 3 Proxies for Expected Surplus, Specific Investments, and Uncertainty in the NFL and the Franchise Contracts .................................. 17 Table 4 Binomial Regressions: Dependent Variables (Contract Length of the NFL Contracts) ................................................ 21 Table 5 Poisson Regressions: Dependent Variables (Contract Length of the Franchise Contracts) .......................................... 25 Table 6 Summary Statistics: Means and Standard Deviations ................................ 36 Table 7 Summary Statistics by Coal Production Region ...................................... 39 Table 8 Contract Duration by Pricing Provision: Means and Standard Deviations. . . . . ...40 Table 9: OLS and MLE (Truncated, Poisson, and Zero-Truncated Poisson Regressions): Dependant Variable (Contract Duration) .................... 45 Table 10 Multinomial Logit Regression: Dependent Variable (Pricing Provision). . . . . ...50 Table 11 The Choice between Pricing Provision Pairs estimated by Multinomial Logit Model ................................................................. 74 Table 12 Seemly Unrelated Regression: Dependent Variables (Contract Duration and Pricing Provisions) ............................................ 53 Table 13 Correlation Matrix of Residuals from the Seemly Unrelated Regression ...... 54 Table 14: Descriptive Statistics (Means and Standard Deviations) ......................... 64 Table 15 Binomial Regression and Probit Models ............................................. 68 vi LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1 Contract Length of the NFL Contracts ................................................ 10 Figure 2 Average Contract Length and the Proportion of Non-Division IA (N on-DIVIA) School Graduates ......................................................... 10 Figure 3 Percentage of Building Types Allowed for Franchise Outlet ...................... 14 Figure 4 Percentage of Franchisors by Business Sector ................. I ...................... 1 4 Figure 5 Contract Duration of the Coal Contract ................................................ 38 Figure 6 Average Contract Duration by Year ................................................... 38 Figure 7 The US. Bureau of Mines Coal-producing Districts ................................ 38 Figure 8 Number of Years Agent Certified Prior to Draft for the 2001-2007 Contracts .................................................................. 66 vii INTRODUCTION In this dissertation, I empirically test the implications fiom the theory of economic institutions, using information on non-monetary contract terms. Specifically, in the first chapter, Contract Length: Expected Surplus, Specific Investments, and Uncertainty, I empirically test how contract length is affected by expected surplus, specific investments, and uncertainty. Using the contract information from the National Football League and the franchising industry, I find that contract length increases with expected surplus and specific investments. In addition, contract length increases with uncertainty when the seller (player) is more risk averse than the buyer (team), and decreases with uncertainty when the seller (franchisor) is less risk averse than the buyer (franchisee). In the second chapter, The Choice of Contract Duration and Pricing Provision in the Coal Markets, I look at the contract terms of the coal contracts from 1979 to 2001. Joskow (1987) examined the importance of specific investments to the contract duration of coal contracts. Since different price—adjust mechanisms are adopted and provide different incentives for the contracting parties over a long-term relationship, this chapter examines the choice of contract duration as well as pricing provision of the coal contracts. In addition to J oskow's finding that contract duration increases with specific investments, the empirical results show that coal contract duration increases with expected surplus and decreases with uncertainty. Moreover, the same determinants are also found to affect the choice probability among different pricing provisions. The simultaneous estimation confirms the empirical results are not significantly changed by the simultaneity between the choice of contract duration and pricing provision. In the third chapter, The Eflect of an Agent’s Experience on National Football League Contract Structure, we use contract information on players drafted before and after the implementation of the NFL salary cap and finds that experienced agents are more likely to negotiate shorter contracts and are more likely have protracted negotiations that extend beyond the start of the NFL team’s training camp. Our results also suggest that, prior to the NFL salary cap, experienced agents were more likely to negotiate contracts that include an incentive clauses. While our results indicate that the contract structure and negotiation process vary systematically with the experience level of the player’s agent, we are unable to infer from these results whether it is in the player’s best interest to hire an experienced agent. CHAPTER I CONTRACT LENGTH: EXPECTED SURPLUS, SPECIFIC INVESTMENTS, AND UNCERTAINTY. INTRODUCTION Why do some contracts have longer duration than other contracts? In a world with unforeseeable contingencies, writing a complete contract is virtually impossible. Every contract negotiation has to decide the duration of the relationship, considering the tradeoffs associated with contract length such as renegotiation cost and flexibility in the future. However, the empirical literature testing contract theory provides thin evidence on the determinants of contract length due to the focus on incentive contracts and firm boundaries.l Since contract length is one of the most important parameters of nearly every contract, this paper provides evidence on how expected surplus, specific investments and uncertainty affect the length of commercial and labor contracts. Most of the research on contract length falls into the literature of transaction cost theory, or incomplete contract theory.2 The central issue is how specific investments relate to contract length. In particular, Klein, Crawford, and Alchian (1978, hereafter Ii I am grateful to my advisor, Mike Conlin, for his continuous guidance and support to this project. I also thank Thomas Jeitschko, Jay Wilson, Kent Miller, Jeff Wooldridge, and Jay Pil Choi for their suggestions, as well as Rob Bond for his expertise on the franchising industry. All errors are mine. Financial support from the Department of Economics at Michigan State University is greatly appreciated. ' See Chiappori and Salanié (2003) for a survey on testing contract theory, and Lafontaine and Slade (2007) for a survey on the empirical literature of vertical integration. While the career concerns literature also addresses the problem by relating long-term contracts with the moral hazard problem, it also falls into the literature of incentive contract. For example, see the textbook treatment by Bolton and Dewatripont (2005, .470) See Guriev and Kvasov (2005) for a summary of the theoretical literature on contact length and specific investments, and Shelanski and Klein (1995) for a survey on the empirical literature. KCA) argued that if a long-term contract specifying the terms of fiiture transactions can be provided ex ante, the level of opportunistic behavior can be mitigated ex post and thus the specific investment can be made more efficient.3 The prediction has been tested in primarily commercial contracts. For example, Joskow (1987) first tested the prediction using the contracts between coal suppliers and electric utilities. He found that the more important are specific investments, the longer the contract. Similar evidence is also found in natural gas contracts (Crocker and Masten, 1988), franchise contracts (Brickley, Misra, and Van Horn, 2006, hereafter BMV) and tenancy agreements (Bandiera, 2007), among others. The research relating contract length to uncertainty consists of labor and macroeconomics literature that focuses on how longer contracts trade off the cost of inflexibility against the cost of renegotiation. Theoretically, this relationship is ambiguous. While Gray (1978) and Dye (1985) suggest that contract length is negatively related to uncertainty, Harris and Hohnstrom (1987) and Danziger (1988) find that contract length is positively related to uncertainty. The negative relationship argument is supported by the eflicient production hypothesis, which indicates the contract wage will be deviated away from the efficient wage when there is more uncertainty. To make the production more efficiently, contract length should therefore decrease with uncertainty. On the other hand, the positive relationship argument is supported by the eflicient risk- sharing hypothesis (Danziger, 1988).4 The idea is that, when one of the contracting parties is more risk-averse than the other, a longer contract will be more efficient in risk- 3 Cheung (1969) first proposed the idea that the tenancy lease duration is chosen to minimize transaction costs, which is defined as the cost to secure and transfer the right to the income generated by private investment, as well as the renegotiation cost. 4 Harris and Holmstrom (1987), on the other hand, emphasize the relationship between information discovery process and contract duration. sharing when there is more uncertainty. In addition, the empirical literature also finds mixed evidence for the relationship between contract length and uncertainty, using mainly the union-firm labor contracts (Wallace, 2001). While the literature emphases the tradeoff between flexibility and renegotiation cost to use a long-term contract, most of the empirical works focus on the measurement issue on the future uncertainty while the renegotiation cost is given exogenously in the context of labor-union contract.5 In this paper, I argue the amount of expected surplus from the contracting relationship, which is defined as the willingness to pay of the buyer minus the willingness to accept of the seller, provides an indirect measure of the renegotiation cost. When there are more surplus to be generated from the contract, the contracting parties will spend more resources to acquire a bigger portion of pie. The expected surplus therefore increases negotiation cost and contract length. The relationship between expected surplus and contract length is related to the quasi rents mentioned in KCA, but different in the sense that expected surplus is generated even without specific investments. Crocker and Masten (1988) empirically tested the relationship using natural gas contracts and found contract length increases with the quasi rents at stake. This paper empirically tests the effects of expected surplus, specific investments and uncertainty on contract length, using contract information from the National Football League (NFL) and the franchising industry. The benefits of using both types of contracts are threefold. First, this allows us to examine whether the determinants of contract length vary across labor and commercial contracts. Second, while the seller (player) is more risk averse than the buyer (team) in the NFL, the seller (franchisor) is less risk averse than the buyer (franchisee) in the franchising industry. Analyzing both contract environments 5 For example, see Murphy (1992) and Wallace (2001). enables the comparison between two contracting environments with different relative risk attitudes of the buyer and seller. Third, using both types of contracts enables multiple proxies of expected surplus, uncertainty, and specific investments to be applied in the empirical test. The paper proceeds as follows. The next section describes the contract information and institutional details of the NFL and the franchising industry. Section 3 proceeds to argue why contract length is related to expected surplus, specific investments, and uncertainty. Section 4 discusses the empirical strategy, while Section 5 presents the evidence that contract length increases with expected surplus and specific investments. In addition, contract length increases with uncertainty when the seller is more risk-averse than the buyer in the NFL, and decreases as the seller is less risk-averse than the buyer in the fi'anchising industry. Section 6 concludes. DATA AND INSTITUTIONAL DETAILS I use both labor contracts from the NFL and commercial contracts from the franchising industry to test the determinants of contract length. In this section, the data and institutional details are discussed for both industries. National Football League Contracts The NFL conducts their annual draft in late April. There are multiple rounds in a draft, and in each round each team owns one pick to select a player. The order of picks is based on the prior year's performance, with the first pick going to the worst performing team. A team may trade its pick to another team for specific players and/or picks. After being drafted, the draftee and his agent negotiate a contract with the team. The team has exclusive rights on the draftee which prohibits other NFL teams from signing the player. Almost all draftees agree to contractual terms with the NFL team holding their rights. If a draftee is unable to reach a contractual agreement, he can either sit out a year and reenter the subsequent year's draft or play for another professional football league (such as Canadian Football League). The contract information of those players drafted comes from two time periods, 1986-1991 (hereafter 86-91) and 2001-2007 (hereafter 01-07). Every contract specifies the duration of the contract and monetary payments, which includes signing bonus and base salary. Besides early round draft choices in the 01-07 drafts, almost all the contracts are not guaranteed in the sense that the team has the right to cut a player and not pay his base salary. Signing bonus, on the other hand, is guaranteed money and paid upfront. Some contracts also include incentive clauses. After the NFL and the NFL Player's Association (NF LPA) entered into a new collective bargaining agreement (CBA) in 1993, the general structure of the contract has become more varied because of the introduction of salary cap. The salary cap limits team's spending on player salaries with signing bonus prorated evenly over the duration of the contract. The NFLPA provided the contract data, along with players' position, college, selection number in draft, and drafting team. The data include 1,872 contracts fi'om 86-91 and 1,782 contracts from 01-07. There were 28 teams having a single pick in each of the 12 rounds from 86-91, and 32 teams having a single pick in each of the 7 rounds from 01- 07.6 Team information is obtained from the NFL Record and Fact Book (1986-1991, 2000-2007), including team's paid attendance, stadium capacity, win-loss record, and head coach tenure. College teams’ divisions were obtained from the 1995 Official National Collegiate Athletic Association College Football Records Book, where the Division IA schools are the schools with larger budgets for athletic programs than the other schools. At last, the population in the metropolitan statistical areas (MSA) is interpolated/extrapolated from the 1990 and 2000 US. census. 6 There were only 31 teams in 2001 because the Houston Texans joined the NFL in 2002. The Texan's 12 contracts in 2002 are dropped in the regression analysis since there are no observations for the variables related to the prior year. Table 1 Summary Statistics of the NFL Contracts during 1986-1991 and 2001-2007 Variable 1986-1991 2001-2007 Contract length 2.74 3.81 (0.80) (1.02) Proportion of division IA player 0.79 0.91 (0.41) (0.28) Empty seat ratio last year 0.18 0.06 (0.14) (0.08) Average paid attendance last year per home game ( 10,000 seats) 5.31 6.59 (0.92) (0.80) Capacity last year (10,000 seats) 6.80 6.97 ' (0.92) (0.61) Dummy=l if stadium capacity increased more than 1,000 0_07 008 seats from the prior year (0.25) (0.27) Dummy=l if stadium capacity decreased more than 1,000 0,02 0.04 seats from the prior year (0.15) (0.20) Wins last yearA 7,77 7.88 (2.96) (3.05) Head coach tenure 5.72 3.96 (6.38) (3.05) Metropolitan population (1,000,000) 4.78 5.01 (4.94) (4.95) Observations 1 872 1 782a Note: A. Variables related to the prior year have sample size equals 1770. Standard errors in parentheses Table 1 presents the summary statistics for each time period. As the table indicates, the average length of the contracts in the 01-07 dataset is about one year longer than in 86-91. Contract length ranges between one and six years in the 86-91 dataset, and one and seven years in the 01-07 dataset.7 Figure 1 presents the distribution of contract length for both time periods. 7 Section 5 of Article XVII of the 2006 CBA states: “The initial Players Contract of a Rookie, including Figure 1 Contract Length of the NFL Contracts 5; l & 0| 1 i see 4 Proportion oteontracta 8 8 l l Contract Length [in 36-91 I 0107; Figure 2 Average Contract Length and the Proportion of Non-Division IA (Non-DIVIA) School Graduates 6.. 5. 73 i '5 ill ‘0 c < o4 5 -‘1 im it :31 2'0 8 ‘55 o 1: o it s 5 E 1- n. Round — Length(86-9T) LengtrilBi-or) T - - Non-DNIA(86-9t) Non-DNIA(01-07)V any Club option, may not exceed four years in length, except that the initial Player Contract of a Rookie drafted with a selection in the first half of the first round (e.g., the first sixteen of thirty-two selections in the 2006 Draft), including any Club option, may not exceed six years in length, and the initial Player Contract of a Rookie drafted with a selection in the second half of the first round, including any Club option, may not exceed five years in length.” In addition, Figure 2 presents the average contract length by round, as well as the proportion of non-Division IA school draftees by round. Average contract length decreases across rounds and the rate of the decrease is similar across time periods. The fact that signing bonus is allowed to be prorated evenly over the duration of the contract after imposition of the salary cap is one explanation as to why the average contract length in every round is longer for the 01-07 data. Since teams pay more signing bonus instead of salary to the player to save more spending space, they ask for the longer contract with player because the signing bonus is paid upfront. 8 In addition, the number of non- Division IA school draftees increases across rounds for both time periods, while there were more non-Division IA school players drafted in the 86-91 drafts. Summary statistics of the other variables are similar for both time periods, except for the empty seat percentage. The empty seat percentage is much smaller during 01-07 because attendance has increased approximately 24 percent while there was only a three percent increase in the average stadium capacity. Franchise Contracts A franchise contract specifies the agreement on the franchisee's right to use the franchisor's trademark or the right to sell his product in a given place for a specific duration (Lafontaine, 1992). To test the effect of expected surplus, uncertainty, and specific investments on franchise contract duration, I obtained information from the 8 The tradeoff between contract length and signing bonus is discussed in Duberstein (1991 ). 11 Bond's Franchise Guide (Bond, 2007), which includes detailed survey responses from 1,005 franchisors. Table 2 presents the summary statistics.9 Table 2 Summary Statistics of the Franchise Contracts Information from Bond (2007) Variables Mean Length of the initial contract (in year) 11.15 (6.46) Dummy=1 if listed as Top 100 franchisors in 2006 0.10 (0.30) Dummy=1 if allowed building type of unit are home-based or kiosk 0.21 (0.41) Years since first franchised 19.51 ( 12.58) Required total training (in days) 22.82 (25.65) Number of total units (in 1,000) 0-49 ( 1 .98) Dummy=1 if the franchisor is in rental, business aid, or education sectors 0.09 (0.28) Dummy=l if headquartered in a state that restricts contract termination 0-33 (0.47) Observations 1005A Note: A. Sample size varies across variables since some franchisors did not respond to every question in the survey. Standard deviations are in parentheses. The mean duration of the initial contracts is slightly less than eleven years; with 51 percent having ten year durations; nineteen percent having five year durations; and 12 percent having 20 year durations. Table 2 also indicates that ten percent of the fi'anchisors 9 In the survey, a franchisor was asked contact information, background details, required financial and contract terms of his franchisee, specific expansion plans in the near future, as well as the support and training provided for his franchisee. Moreover, instead of a single value response, some franchisors provided a range of values for some financial and contractual variables. In such case the average of the lowest and the highest values are used as their responses. Finally, replies that are ambiguous or a non- response are treated as missing. 12 were listed in Bond's Top 100 franchisors (Bond, 2006).10 In addition, the survey asked each franchisor what building type was allowed for a franchise outlet. Most of the franchisors provided several choices for prospective franchisee, with 21 percent allowing a home-based unit or a kiosk. Figure 3 shows the proportion of franchisors who allow each building type. Moreover, Table 2 reveals that the franchisors have average 20 years of fi'arrchising experience and provide their franchisees an average of 23 days of on- and off-site training.11 The franchisors have on average 492 units in a chain, where 88 percent of the franchisors' units are franchised. Nine percent of the franchisors were in rental, business aid, or educational sectors, and Figure 4 presents the distribution of fianchisors by business sector. Finally, many states in the US. have statues that regulate the franchising industry. Most of these states require good cause for termination and non- renewal of the existing franchising relationship.12 Table 2 indicates that 33 percent of the franchisors are headquartered in the states restricting termination of a franchise contract. '0 Bond '3 Top I 00franchisors broke the franchising industry into food-services, retail, and service-based franchises, evaluated companies on the basis of historical performance, brand identification, market dynamics, franchisee satisfaction, the level of initial training and on-going support, litigation record, and financial stability, etc (Bond 2006). '1 Franchisors responded to this question using different measures, including hours, days, and weeks. All responses are converted into days, where a training day is defined as a business day (8 hours a day, 5 days a week). Moreover, the off-site training includes training at headquarter, training center, classroom, and current operating unit, while the on-site training indicates training at franchisee's own site. '2 A good cause for termination is the franchisee's failure to comply with the material terms of the franchise contract (Blair and Lafontaine, 2005). The sixteen states which limit termination for good cause are Arkansas, California, Connecticut, DC, Delaware, Illinois, Indiana, Iowa, Michigan, Minnesota, Nebraska, New Jersey, Tennessee, Virginia, Washington, and Wisconsin (Klick, Kobayashi, and Ribstein, 2006, Table 4). See also the discussion about contract duration and the termination laws in BMV, footnote 21, and Blair and Lafontaine (2005, p. 279). 13 Proportion of Franchisors Proportlon of franchisors Figure 3 Percentage of Building Types Allowed for Franchise Outlet Building type Figure 4 Percentage of Franchisors by Business Sector 40 35 30 4 25 20 15 - 10 - 5 0 - Others Food service Retail Rental, Auto products Clearing and business aid. and services maintenance and education Business eector l4 HYPOTHESES In this section, I provide the arguments for why contract length is related to expected surplus, specific investments, and uncertainty, using the NFL and franchising contracts as examples. Expected Surplus. Expected surplus is defined as the willingness to pay of the buyer minus the willingness to accept of the seller. More resources will be spent by the contracting parties when there are more surplus to be generated from the contract. Consequently, renegotiation cost is increased with expected surplus. Since contract length increases with renegotiation cost (Dye, 1985), contract length is thus also positively related to expected surplus. For example, the NFL teams often expect more surplus to be generated from their contracts with early draftees than the later ones. It is because the willingness to accept between the early and later draftees are not significantly different due to their limited outside options, while the early draftees can often attract more audience for his team. Consequently, the early draftees usually hire multiple agents to negotiate with the draft team while the later draftees often use a friend or family member as his representative (Conlin, Orsini, and Tang, 2009). The draft team, on the other band, also spends more time in negotiations with the early draftees. In the franchising industry, the willingness to pay of the buyer (potential franchisees) is higher for those good franchisors while the willingness to accept of the seller (franchisors) is similar. Since the good franchisors usually prepare more detailed contracts, franchisees who are interested in joining the chains will also have to spend more time and efforts to go through the terms and make sure of their own rights. 15 Specific Investments. One of the main focus of the transaction cost theory is a long-term contract provides a solution to the holdup problem as mentioned in KCA. The hypothesis is confirmed empirically using evidence mainly from the commercial contract as previously discussed. Since the specific investments are also important to the labor contract, such as the human asset specificity argued by Willamson (1983), contract length is expected to increase with specific investments in the labor contract as well as in the commercial contract. Uncertainty. While both the efficient risk-sharing hypothesis and the efficient production hypothesis have been proposed to explain the relationship between contract length and uncertainty, to use both the contract information from the NFL and the franchising industry allows us to examine both hypotheses at the same time. In the NFL contract negotiations, teams are less risk-averse than players because teams are more financially sufficient and diversified. Teams are thus able to provide a longer contract for players when there is more uncertainty. Players, on the other hand, will accept the contract in exchange of insurance.13 In the franchising industry, franchisees are more risk-averse buyer than the seller because franchisees are often less financially sufficient and diversified relative to franchisors. If the future development of the business is uncertain to the franchisee, a long-term contract increases his risk to be locked-up in an unprofitable relationship. Since the investment will be less efficient when there is more uncertainty, while it is also costly for franchisees to breach the contract, the fianchisee will not want to sign a longer contract when the business is more risky. '3 The fact that the NFL contracts are not guaranteed does not affect the argument because of the positive relationship between long-term contract and signing bonus (Duberstein, 1992). While the contact duration may not provide the actual insurance for player, the more signing bonus associated with the longer contact, which is paid upfront, suggested the compensation for player is provided when they signed a longer contact. 16 EMPIRICAL STRATEGY In this section, I discuss the proxies for expected surplus, specific investments and uncertainty from the NFL and franchising datasets. Table 3 compares these proxies for the two types of contacts. Table 3 Proxies for Expected Surplus, Specific Investments, and Uncertainty in the NFL and the Franchise Contracts . NFL Contracts ""Frauchrs‘ i L Expected 1. Selection number 1n the draft Whether franchisor rs lrsted as Surplus 2. Percentage of empty seats a Top 100 franchisor 3. Team wins prior year Specific Whether player is a quarterback 1. Whether allowable building Investments type for outlet includes home- based or kiosk 2. Number of days of total training Uncertainty Whether player graduated from Whether fi'anchisor is in rental, Division IA school business aid, and education sectors National Football League Contracts Expected Surplus. Player's selection number and team's number of empty seats and wins last year are proxies for expected surplus. Since the team's benefit for an early draftee is higher than a later draftee, while the player's opportunity cost does not vary by the order of pick, the expected surplus is greater for a team and an early draftee. Moreover, a team with more empty seats and/or fewer wins is willing to pay more for an early draftee to make immediate contribution, compare to a team with fewer empty seats 17 and/or more wins last year. If contract length is positively related to expected surplus, an early draftee of a team with more empty seats and/or fewer wins last year should negotiate a longer contract. Specific Investments. We use whether a player’s position is quarterback as a proxy for specific investments. Compared to other positions, a quarterback requires more team-specific training because he must learn the team's offensive system and play calling. More team resources are thus invested in the quarterback than the other positions. Since contract length is expected to increase with firm-specific investment, a quarterback's contract should be longer than the contract for other positions. Uncertainty. Whether a player attended a Division IA school is a proxy for uncertainty, since the NFL performance of non-Division IA draftee is more uncertain to team. Players from those small programs went through less intensive games with fewer resources for training, compare to their bigger school counterparts.14 Because the team is less risk averse than the player, contract duration should be greater for draftees that attended non-Division IA school. Franchise Contracts Expected Surplus. Whether a franchisor is selected in the Bond's Top 100 franchisors is a proxy for expected surplus. Franchisee's benefit from joining the chains of those Top 100 franchisors will likely be higher than other franchisors' chains. More expected surplus is therefore generated from contracting with the Top 100 franchisors, 14 The same uncertainty measure has been used by Hendricks, DeBrock, and Koenker (2003). See footnote seven in their paper for more discussion on the uncertainty proxy. 18 since the franchisor's opportunity cost is not likely to vary significantly across franchisees. Consequently, contract duration for the Top 100 franchisors should be greater. Specific Investments. Whether a franchisor allows a home-based unit or a kiosk for outlet is a proxy for specific investments, since the sunk cost of a home-based unit or a kiosk is likely less than for other building types. In addition, since much of the training is firm-specific, the number of required training days is another proxy for specific investments. 1 5 Uncertainty. Since a franchisee is likely more risk averse than the franchisor, contract length is expected to decrease with uncertainty. To measure the risk incurred by a franchisee, Lafontaine and Bhattacharyya (1995) used the yearly average proportion of discontinued outlets between 1982 and 1986 in each sector as a measure of risk faced by a prospective franchisee.‘6 They found the top three sectors with the highest discontinued outlets during 1982 to 1986 were rental service, business aids, and educational products and services sectors.l7 Accordingly, whether franchisor is in those three business sectors is applied as a proxy for uncertainty. '5 BMV used the amount of off-site training as a proxy for human capital investment. Other than the firm- specific training, they also emphasized the amount of travel and opportunity cost the franchisee incurs. Since the focus of this paper is investment specificity, the required total training better serves the purpose. Similar empirical results can be obtained if the off-site training is used as the proxy for uncertainty. '6 See Lafontaine and Bhattacharyya (1995) for other risk measures used in the literature. '7 Lafontaine and Bhattacharyya (1995) obtained the data from Franchising in the Economy, published by US. Department of Commerce, which is not available afier 1986. 19 EMPIRICAL RESULTS National Football League Contracts To test whether contract duration is affected by expected surplus, uncertainty, and specific investments, I regress NFL contract length on player's selection number, team’s empty seats percentage, team wins the prior year, whether the draftee attended a non- Division IA school, as well as the team's MSA population, head coach tenure, prior year's stadium capacity, and whether stadium capacity has increased or decreased by more than 1,000 seats. Team fixed effect, as well as player's position, draft round, and draft year fixed effects are also included in the regression.‘8 Binomial regression is applied for the estimation, since contract duration ranges discretely from one to seven.19 To be specific, the conditional mean to be estimated is assumed as E(lengthilxi)=P(Xil3)L, where x,- denotes the set of regressors; p(x,-B) is a logistic distribution;20 and L is the maximum contract length. Since contract length is restricted, multiplying the estimated probability by L guarantees the fitted value will not exceed the sample range. '8 The empirical results are similar if different sets of fixed effects are applied. To be specific, instead of including all fixed effects in the regression, I have also run the regression with different combinations of fixed effects, including 1) draft round only; 2) draft round and player's position; 3) draft round, player's position, and draft year. 9 The other three possible choices for estimation are ordinary least square (OLS), ordered probit regression, and Poisson regression. The problem of OLS estimation is that it may predict the fitted value to be more than seven or less than zero. The ordered probit regression is not used since there is no data censoring problem in the contracts used here, which is a common problem in the empirical contract duration literature mentioned by Masten and Saussier (2000). At last, by using Poisson regression, the fitted value is assured to be positive but larger than the upper bound of the variable. While only the results from binomial regression are reported, they are robust to these different estimation methods. 20 Table 4 Binomial Regressions: Dependent Variables (Contract Length of the NFL Contracts) , ~ .- i ' 1986—1991 , 2001:2007 Independent . ' -. ,. - ' . q . variables (1) (2) (3.). (4) 7 (5) .’ a (6), . l_' , Selection number -0.004*** -0.003** -0.005*** -0.002* -0.001 —0.002** in the drafi (0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) Empty seats 0.112 0.380” 0.108 -0.215 0.346 -0.196 percentage in home (0.132) (0.166) (0.132) (0.185) (0.286) (0.183) games last year Empty seats -0.002*** -0.004*** percentage in home (0.001) (0.002) game last year" selection number in the draft Number of team 0.000 0.001 -0.008 -0.007* -0.008** -0.029**"‘ wins last year (0.005) (0.005) (0.007) (0.004) (0.004) (0.008) Number of team 0055* 0157*" wins last year prior (0.029) (0.044) to drafi“ selection number in the draft divided by 1,000 Dummy=1 if -0.054“'** -0.055**"‘ -0.055"‘** -0.027 -0.026 -0.026 graduated from (0.019) (0.019) (0.019) (0.031) (0.031) (0.031) Division IA school Dummy=1 if -0.031 -0.030 -0.032 0.097“ 0.095” 0.084“ player is (0.049) (0.048) (0.048) (0.047) (0.046) (0.046) QuarterbackA Metropolitan -0.l61*** -0.159""""l -0. 160*" 0.028 0.028 0.027 population (0.054) (0.055) (0.054) (0.033) (0.033) (0.033) (1,000,000 person) Number of head 0.013*** 0013*" 0013*" 0.007 0.007 0.006 coach tenure at (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) drafi year Stadium capacity -0.071 -0.054 -0.069 0.016 0.020 0.016 of team last year (0.044) (0.046) (0.044) (0.037) (0.049) (0.036) (10,000 seats) Stadium capacity -0.097 -0.062 of team last year (0.090) (0.235) (10,000 seats)* selection number in the draft divided by 1,000 2° The marginal effects are similar if the probability function is assumed to be Gaussian. 21 Table 4 (cont’d) Dummy=1 if -0.040 —0.042 -0.040 -0.099*** -0.103*** -O.102*** stadium capacity (0.049) (0.048) (0.049) (0.032) (0.032) (0.032) increased more than 1,000 seats from the prior year Dummy=1 if 0105* -0.109* -0.106* -0.051 -0.050 -0.050 stadium capacity (0.058) (0.057) (0.058) (0.039) (0.039) (0.039) reduced more than 1,000 seats from last year Indicator variablesB YES YES YES YES YES YES Observations 1872 1872 1872 1770 1770 1 7 70 R-squaredc 0.65 0.66 0.66 0.68 0.68 0.68 Ljog-likelihood -2255.13 -2254.14 -2254.83 -2292.87 -2292.00 -2291.23 Note: A. The coefficients were estimated relatively to the position of defensive linebacker. B. The indicator variables include the draft round, player’s position, draft year, and draft team fixed effects. C. R-squared is the squared correlation coefficient between the observed and the fitted values of the contract length variable. The coefficient estimates are not marginal effects. Robust standard errors presented in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Columns (1) and (4) of Table 4 present the coefficient estimates from this baseline regression.21 The coefficient estimates support the conjecture that, when the buyer is less risk averse than the seller, contract length increases with expected surplus, uncertainty, and specific investments. First, the selection number of player has a negative and statistically significant coefficient for both time periods. If a player was drafted 20 picks later within a round, the duration of his contract will be reduced by about 0.1 years for both time periods. Notice the coefficient estimates were obtained conditional on the round fixed effects. The round dummy coefficients suggests that, compared to players drafted in other rounds, the first round draftees obtained an average of 0.57 year longer 2‘ The coefficient estimates reported in Table 4 are not marginal effects. To calculate the marginal effect of a continuous variable from the binomial regression, the partial derivative of the probability function with respect to the regressor is evaluated at the sample mean of all regressors. For a dummy variable, the marginal effect is evaluated as the difference between the estimated probability when the dummy equals one and when it equals zero. 22 contract during 86—91, and 2.17 years during 01-07. The result indicates contract length increases with expected surplus. In addition, the coefficient on empty seats percentage and number of team wins in prior season vary in Sign with the only statistically significant coefficient being the negative coefficient associated with wins for the 01-07 drafts. 22 Second, players from small schools obtained on average 0.08 year longer contracts than their big school counterparts during 86-91, and 0.04 year longer contracts during 01-07. The coefficient estimates indicate that, when the buyer is less risk averse than the seller, contract length increases with the uncertainty. The result is not statistically significant in the 01-07 dataset because only nine percent of draftees graduated from small schools during 01-07, while 21 percent of draftees were from small schools during 86-91. Third, comparing to other positions, a quarterback had the second shortest contract in the 86-91 dataset, but the longest one in the 01-07 dataset. Since players rarely changed teams unless via a trade prior to the 1993 CBA, the holdup issue is more of a concern in the later years.23 Regressions (2) and (5) of Table 4 include an interaction of empty seats and selection number. An interaction of the stadium capacity last year and selection number is also included as a covariate. As discussed in section 4, the effect of prior year wins and empty seats on contract length may differ for early and late draftees becauSe early draftees are more likely to make an immediate contribution to team performance. The empirical evidence supports this conjecture. All else equal, the empty seats percentage in 22 All else equal, one percentage increase of empty seats in the prior year is related to a 0.17 year longer contract in the 86-91 dataset, but a 0.38 year shorter contract in the 01-07 dataset. On the other hand, one more winning game in the prior year relates to 0.002 year longer contract in the 86-91 dataset, but 0.012 year shorter contract in the 01-07 dataset. 3 For example, the baseline regression indicates a quarterback has an average of 0. l 3 year longer contract than other positions during 01-07. By using the same specification but excluding the position fixed effect, the regression shows a quarterback has on average 0.05 year shorter contract than other positions during 86-91, but 0.07 year longer contract during 01-07. 23 prior season is positively related to contract length, but the effect decreases with the selection number.24 Similarly, regressions (3) and (6) of Table 4 include the interaction term between the number of wins last year and selection number. Compared to other teams, a team with fewer wins last year signed longer contracts with early draftees but shorter contracts with later draftees.25 These results provide further supports that contract length increases with expected surplus. Franchise Contracts To test whether franchise contract length is affected by expected surplus, specific investments, and uncertainty, I regress contract length on whether the franchisor was listed in Bond's Top 100 fianchisors, whether the franchisor allows a home-based unit or a kiosk as an outlet, the number of days of total training, and whether the fi'anchisor is in the retail, business aid, or education industry. The other covariates are the number of units in a chain, the number of years since the franchisor first franchised, and whether franchisor is headquartered in a state that restricts termination of a franchise contract.26 Since lengths are often much longer for franchise compared to NFL contracts, Poisson regression is an appropriate estimation method.27 In particular, the conditional mean is 2“ For example, longer contracts were signed by the teams with more empty seats last year in the 86-91 dataset, but the same teams signed shorter contracts with the draftees after the 190th pick. 25 For example, shorter contracts were signed by the teams with more wins last year in the 01-07 dataset, but the same teams signed longer contracts with the draftees after the 185th pick. 26 BMV applied the number of total units and the number of years since first franchised as the proxies for learning. They argued franchisor with more experience and units in a chain is able to learn more about the optimal contract terms. The contract length will be longer since the franchisor does not need the flexibility to adjust the contract terms. 27 Similar results can be found by using OLS or binomial regressions. 24 E(lengthilxi)=exp(xifl), where x,- denotes the set of regressors, and length,- given x,- has a Poisson distribution. Table 5 Poisson Regressions: Dependent Variables (Contract Length of the Franchise Contracts) Independent variables (1) (2) Dummy=1 if listed as Top 100 franchisors in 2006 0133*" 0179*" (0.061) (0.053) Dummy=1 if allowable building type of unit are home-based or kiosk -0149":- 41113" (0.049) (0.057) Number of days of required total training 0002*" 0.002" (0.001) (0.001) Dummy=l if the franchisor is in rental, business aid, or education sectors 0227*" .0,420*** (0.060) (0.082) Number of total units divided by 1,000 0,007 0,014“ (0.007) (0.007) Number of years since first fianchisedl 0004*" 0,002 (0.001) (0.001) Dummy=l if located in the state requires good cause for termination 0.089" 0100*" (0.040) (0.037) Business sector fixed effect NO YES Observations 848 848 R-squaredA .09 .25 Log-likelihood -2815.21 -2620.45 Note: A. R-squared is the squared correlation coefficient between the observed and the fitted values of the contract length variable. The coefficient estimates are not marginal effects. Robust standard errors presented in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Table 5 presents the coefficient estimates from this specification. These estimates are similar whether or not business sector fixed effects are included. The empirical results support the hypothesis that, when the buyer is more risk averse than the seller, contract length increases with greater expected surplus, less uncertainty, and more specific 25 investments. First, all else equal, franchisors listed in the Bond's Top 100 franchisors provided about 18 percent longer contract than other franchisors, and this difference is statistically significant. The results also indicate that franchisors offered longer contract when there was greater expected surplus. Second, the franchisors in rental, business aid, and education industry provided 42 percent shorter contract than other franchisors. This statistically significant difference suggests that, when the buyer is more risk averse than the seller, contract length decreases with the uncertainty. Finally, if a franchisor allows a home-based unit or a kiosk as a franchise outlet, the franchisor on average provides a 12 percent shorter contract. If a franchisor reduces the required total training by a day, contract length on average shorten by 0.2 percent. These estimates are statistically significant and provide the evidence that contract length increases with specific investments, which is consistent with the literature. 26 CONCLUSION The existing research testing contract theory provides limited evidence on the determinants of contract length. The effects of uncertainty and specific investments on contract length have also been tested separately on labor and commercial contracts, respectively. This is the first paper to address the relationship between expected surplus and contract length, and tests the determinants of contract length for both commercial and labor contracts using NFL and franchising data. The empirical evidence indicates that contract length increases with expected surplus and specific investments. In addition, contract length increases with uncertainty when the seller (player) is more risk averse than the buyer (team), and decreases with uncertainty when the seller (franchisor) is less risk averse than the buyer (franchisee). Further research is required to see if these relationships hold for other types of commercial and labor contracts. 27 REFERENCES Bandiera, Oriana. "Contract Duration and Investment Incentives: Evidence from Land Tenancy Agreements," Journal of the European Economic Association, 2007, 5(5), pp. 953-86. Blair, Rogert D. and Lafontaine, Francine. The Economics of Franchising, 2005, Cambridge University Press. Bolton, Patrick and Dewatripont, Mathias. Contract Theory, 2005, The MIT Press. Bond, Robert E., et al. Bond '3 Franchise Guide, 2007, Source Book Publications. --------- . Bond's Top 100 Franchises, 2006, Source Book Publications. Brickley, James A.; Misra Sanjog; and Van Horn, R. Lawrence. "Contract Duration: Evidence from Franchising," The Journal of Law and Economics, 2006, 49(1), pp. 173-96. Cheung, Steven N.S. "Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements," The Journal of Law and Economics, 1969, 12(1), pp. 23-42. Chiappori, Pierre-Andre and Salanié, Bernard. "Testing Contract Theory: 3 Survey of Some Recent Work," CESifo Working Paper Series No. 738, 2002, SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=3 l 8780 Collective Bargaining Agreement (CBA): between The NFL Management Council and The NFL Players Association, March 8, 2006. http://wwwnflplayers.com/user/template.aspx?fmid=l 8 l &lmid=622&pid=0&typ e=l Conlin, Mike; Orsini, Joe and Tang, Meng-Chi. "The Effect of an Agent's Experience on National Football League Contract Structure," Michigan State University Working paper. 28 Crocker, Keith J. and Masten, Scott E. "Mitigating Contractual Hazards: Unilateral Options and Contract Length," RAND Journal of Economics, 1988, 19(3), pp. 327-43. Danziger, Leif. "Real Shocks, Efficient Risk Sharing, and the Duration of Labor Contracts," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1988, 103(2), pp. 435-40. Duberstein, M. J ., “On the Sidelines: An Annual Economic Analysis of the National Football League Prepared for Members of the NFL Players Association,” National Football League Association, 1992. Dye, Ronald. "Optimal Length of Labor Contracts," International Economic Review, 1985, 26(1), pp. 251-70. Gray, J o A. "On Indexation and Contract Length," Journal of Political Economy, 1978, 86(1), pp. 1-18. Guriev, Sergei and Kvasov, Dmitriy. "Contracting on Time," American Economic Review, 2005, 95(5), pp. 1369-85. Harris, Milton and Holmstrom, Bengt. "On the Duration of Agreements," International Economic Review, 1987, 28(2), pp. 389-406. Hendricks, Wallace; DeBrock, Lawrence and Koenker, Roger. "Uncertainty, Hiring, and Subsequent Performance: The NFL Draft," Journal of Labor Economics, 2003, 21(4), pp. 857-86. J oskow, Paul L. "Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence from Coal Markets," American Economic Review, 1987, 77(1), pp. 168- 85. Klein, Benjamin; Crawford, Robert G. and Alchian, Armen A. "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," The Journal of Law and Economics, 1978, 21(2), pp. 297-326. Klick, Jonathan; Kobayashi, Bruce H. and Ribstein, Larry E. "The Effect of Contract 29 Regulation: The Case of Franchising," George Mason Law & Economics Research Paper No. 07-03, SSRN: http://Ssrn.com/abstract=951464. Lafontaine, Francine. "Agency Theory and Franchising: Some Empirical Results," RAND Journal of Economics, 1992, 23(2), pp. 263-83. --------- . and Bhattacharyya, Sugato. "The Role of Risk in Franchising," Journal of Corporate Finance, 1995, 2, 39-74. --------- . and Slade, Margaret. "Vertical Integration and Firm Boundaries: The Evidence," Journal of Economic Literature, 2007, 45(3), pp. 629-85. Masten, Scott E. and Saussier, Stephane. "Econometrics of Contracts: An Assessment of Developments in the Empirical Literature on Contracting," Revue d'Economie Industrielle, 2000, 92, pp. 215-36. Murphy, Keven J. "Detemimants of Contract Duration in Collective Bargaining Agreements," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 1992, 45(2), pp. 352-65. Vézquez, Luis. "Determinants of Contract Length in Franchise Contracts," Economics Letters, 2007, 97, pp. 145-50. Wallace, Frederick H. "The Effects of Shock Size and Type on Labor-Contract Duration," Journal of Labor Economics, 2001, 19(3), pp. 658-81. Williamson, Oliver E. "Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange," American Economic Review, 1983, 73, pp. 519-40. 30 CHAPTER II THE CHOICE OF CONTRACT DURATION AND PRICING PROVISION IN THE COAL MARKETS‘ INTRODUCTION In his seminal paper, Joskow (1987) provided the empirical evidence supporting the importance of specific investments to contract duration, using 277 contracts fi'om the coal markets. His paper confirms the hypothesis proposed by Klein, Crawford, and Alchian (1978) and Williamson (1983) that long-term contracts provide the incentive for more efficient relationship-specific investment by reducing the possibility of ex post opportunism behavior or the holdup problem. However, J oskow (1987) did not consider the simultaneity between the choices of contract duration and pricing provision. Different pricing provisions are used in the coal market (Joskow, 1985, 1988), and different price- adjustrnent mechanisms reduce the costs of signing a long-term contract while preserving the benefits of such contract. To be specific, a long-term contract saves renegotiation costs and induces more efficient specific investments, but also reduces the flexibility of the contracting parties when facing fiiture contingencies. It is therefore important to apply appropriate pricing provision to maximize the expected revenue generated from the contract over a long-term relationship, subject to the flexibility constraint. For example, if a fixed price is negotiated for trading a certain good over multiple years, it will not be easy for the contracting parties to accommodate the future contingencies. However, if a . I thank Mike Conlin, Thomas Jeitschko, Jay Wilson, and Kent Miller for their comments and suggestions, as well as George Warholic for his expertise in the coal industry. 31 price-adjust mechanism is included in the contract, such as designing the price as a fimction of current consumer price index, the contract price can therefore automatically reflect the current market situation. In this paper, I examine the choice of contract duration and pricing provision simultaneously, using more than 5,000 observations from coal markets. Most of the related literature focus on the choice of pricing provision, while relatively fewer researches look at the choice of contract duration and the joint decision of pricing provision and contract duration. 28 The choice of contract type has been examined in multiple industries, including timber-harvesting (Leffler and Rucker, 1991), natural gas (Crocker and Masten, 1991), jet engine procurement (Crocker and Reynolds, 1993), and tenancy (Bandiera, 2007).29 The main question is how to design a long-term contract that incorporates the flexibility for future adjustment and reduces the possibility of potential opportunism, and retains the benefits of maintaining a long-term relationship.30 While the empirical results are industry-dependent, the available evidence in general confirms the importance of uncertainty and specific investments to the design of pricing provision of the long-term contracts. Contract duration has been examined separately on commercial contracts and labor-union contracts, focusing on the effect fiom specific investments and uncertainty, respectively. The relationship between contract duration and specific investments has always been the focus of the transaction cost theory, and the idea has been tested using the commercial contracts, such as coal contracts (J oskow, 1987) and natural gas contracts 28 Crocker (1996) reviewed some related works on the choice of contract duration and pricing provision by public utilities. 9 For more detailed review, see Masten and Saussier (2000) and Masten (2000). 3° Cheung (1969) argued that the choice of contractual arrangement is made so as to maximize the gain from risk dispersion subject to the constraint of transaction costs. 32 (Crocker and Masten, 1988). The consensus from the existing evidence is that contract duration increases with specific investments. The labor-union contract, on the other hand, has been used mainly by the macroeconomics literature to test how the future uncertainty affects the negotiated contract duration (Wallace, 2001). While the empirical evidence on the effect is mixed, Tang (2009) argued the relationship between contract duration and uncertainty depends on the relative risk attitude between the buyer and seller. Using contracts from the franchising industry and the National Football League, he also found the expected surplus generated from the contracting relationship is the other factor that positively relates to the contract duration. While Masten and Saussier (2000) note that a few papers address the simultaneity concern between contract duration and pricing provision design, Bandiera (2007) is a notable exception. In addition to the typical focus of the literature on the tenancy contractual choice, Bandiera (2007) estimates the determinants of contract duration jointly with contract type. She found both the contract duration and contract type are affected by the wealth of the tenant and the type of the crops, which indicates the importance of specific investments and flexibility to the tenancy contract design. On the other hand, instead of jointly estimating the duration and pricing provision, Crocker and Masten (1991) also incorporates the effect fiom contract duration when looking at the pricing provision choice of the natural gas contract. They addressed the simultaneity issue using an instrumental variable regression and found strong correlation between contract duration, uncertainty and pricing provision. Nevertheless, they found no significant effects from specific investments to the contract design. 33 This paper examines the choice of coal contract duration and pricing provision in the coal markets, and proceeds as follows: the next section describes the data. Section 3 discusses and empirically tests the determinants of contract duration. The results indicate coal contract duration increases with expected surplus and specific investments, and decreases with uncertainty. Section 4 argues the different costs and benefits behind different pricing provisions over a long-term relationship, and empirically tests the determinants of the pricing provision choice. I find the determinants that affect contract duration also affect the choice of pricing provision. Section 5 estimates the choices of contract duration and pricing provision simultaneously. The empirical results with the simultaneity consideration are not significantly different from the estimates obtained in the previous sections. Section 6 concludes. 34 DATA AND INSTITUTIONAL DETAILS In this paper, I focus on the contract arrangement of coal delivery between electric utilities and coal suppliers.31 I use the data from the Coal Transportation Rate Database (CTRD).32 The CTRD contains coal supply contract data between each utility and coal supplier, includes contract terms, plant, route, and transportation-related information.33 The primary source for the CTRD is from Federal Energy Regulatory Commission's Form 580, which requires responses fiom all jurisdictional utilities that either operate or have ownership interest in at least one steam-electric generating station with a capacity of 50 megawatts or greater}4 The CTRD contains the information of 2,980 contracts for 141 utilities and 384 plants thru 1979-2001, provides an origin-to-destination record for every route over which that plant's coal flows. Because one coal supply contract can serve several plants and contain different routes for the same coal delivery with different contract terms, I use each coal flow as the unit of observation rather than the contract per se. Twenty three percent of the observations were signed before 1979, indicates some contracts were executed before the sampling period. In addition, a coal flow can be observed repeatedly across the sample years but only the first record is used for 3 ' For detailed overview of the coal industry, see Joskow (1985). 32 The data can be obtained from http://www.eia.doe.gov/cneaf/coal/ctrdb/database.html. For detailed description, see Warholic (2004). 33 An observation in the CT RD identifies the parties involved in the contracting relationship (the utility company, the utility plant, the coal supplier, the mines that provided coal), the agreed duration of the relationship, the upper and lower limits of the agreed quantity to be shipped, the agreed coal quality specification (the upper and lower limits of Sulphur, Ash, and Moisture), the coal rate information, and the transportation information (the geographic information of the delivery, the number of routes used, the modes of transportation used for each route, and the rate for each transportation mode). Each observation also indicates whether the plant is a mine-mouth plant, and whether the utility company owns the transportation mode that is being used for delivery. 3" Jurisdictional utility is defined as the facilities involved in the transmission of electric energy in interstate commerce and the sale of electric power at wholesale in interstate commerce. Also see http://www.ferc.gov/docs-filing/hard-filing/form—580/overview.asp for more information about Form 580. 35 analysis.35 I also exclude 1,669 observations with incomplete information on contract length and 61 observations with incomplete information on the coal production region or the coal is obtained outside the North America. . Table 6 Summary Statistics: Means and Standard Deviations Variable Contract Duration (years) 8.493 (9.647) Mine-Mouth Plant (=1 if the plant is a mine-mouth plant, 0 otherwise) 0.006 (0.078) Total Number of Contracts Signed between the Same Plant and Supplier 3.027 (2.921) Minimum Annual Contract Quantity (trillion Btu’s) 15.171 (19.960) Percentage of Sulfur of the Coal Shipped 1.333 (0.943) Percentage of Ash of the Coal Shipped 9.452 (3.1 10) Percentage of Moisture of the Coal Shipped 9.925 (8.3 14) Total Distance of A Route (1,000 miles) 0.439 (0.428) Total Number of Observations 5,835 Table 6 presents the summary statistics. There are 5,835 observations from 2,649 contracts with 116 utilities, 344 plants, and 730 coal suppliers. During the sample period, about 65 percent and 73 percent of the observations are the first contract observed between the same utility and supplier and the same plant and supplier, respectively. The 35 A coal flow in the sample has been observed on average six times during the sample period. 13,071 observations are dropped. 36 average contract duration is 8.5 years. About half of the observations have a length equal or less than five years, while five percent of the observations have contract length less than a year. The later is treated as spot purchase and recorded with zero duration. Figure 5 shows the distribution of the contract duration. In addition, Figure 6 indicates there is a decreasing trend of contract length across sample years. 36 In addition, 0.6% of the observed coal flows are directed to mine-mouth plants, which are the plants that located next to specific mines in anticipation of taking all or most of their requirements from that mine.37 A plant on average signed three contracts with the same supplier during the sample period in the sequential years. The minimum annual contract quantity is on average 15.17 trillion Btu's. Table 6 also presents the characteristics of the coal shipped. I use the shipped coal quality rather than the agreed coal quality because more than half of the observations do not have the latter information. At last, the average distance of a route for coal delivery is 439 miles. Up to four transportation facilities used for delivery are recorded in the CTRD, and more than 68% of the coal deliveries used rail.38 Sixty- three percent of the coal deliveries used only one transportation mode. About 10% of the utility companies own the transportation facility for coal delivery. 3" As Warholic (2004) pointed out, coal customers preferred shorter terms of contracts in recent years because of the expectation of declining coal prices. 37 Joskow (1987, pp. 170) provided the definition of mine-mouth plant. The CT RD identifies 36 coal flows to mine-mouth plants. 33The other choices are barge, collier, truck, conveyor, and pipeline. 37 Figure 5 Contract Duration of the Coal Contract Figure 6 Average Contract Duration by Year 3... a8“ - C 3 o. o E . o_ o w U E .'. . s o o " q. :8" . ..-.... 0.. ‘00,. 0 ca m l l l l l l l I l 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 The Year Contract Signed Figure 7 The U.S. Bureau of Mines Coal-producing Districts 38 The characteristics of coal production and transportation availability vary across different regions. Using the U.S. Bureau of Mines (BOM) coal-producing districts definition shown in Figure 7, production occurs in three regions: East, Midwest, and West.39 In general, coal quality is more uniformly distributed in the East than the West. The East also has more abundant transportation alternatives for delivery than the West. In both cases, the Midwest is somewhere in between. 40 Table 7 shows the summary statistics by region. Twenty percent of the coal supply in the data is from the West, which has the longest average contract length and distance per route. Most of the mine-mouth plants in the sample are located in the West. Table 7 Summary Statistics by Coal Production Region Region West Midwest East Average Contract Duration (years) 10.938 9.186 7.573 (13.054) (9.297) (8.213) Total Number of Mine-Mouth Plants 18 8 10 Average Distance of A Route (1,000 miles) 0.934 0.245 0.327 @490) (0.362) (0.280) Total Number of Observations 1,195 834 3,806 Note: Standard deviations are in parenthesis. Various pricing provisions of contract are used in the coal industry. 41 The simplest versions are fixed price contract with the price fixed over the life of the contract, and market price contract with the delivery price fluctuates with spot market. The other 39 Figure 3 is obtained from http://www.eia.doe.gov/cneaf/coal/page/districts/coaldistricts.htrnl. I use the definition by Joskow (1987, pp. 184). The Energy Information Administration names the regions as Appalachia, Interior, and Western. Sixty-one percent of total observations are dropped due to lack of this information or the source mines are not included in those regions. 4° For more details, see Joskow (1985, 1987). 4' Federal Energy Regulatory Commission provides the definition of the coal contract types in the Form 580, which is obtained from http://www.ferc.gov/docs-filing/hard-filing/form-S80/overview.asp. See also Joskow (1985, 1988) for more details on the types of coal contracts. 39 contract types, which incorporate some price adjustment mechanisms, are cost plus contract, base price plus escalation contract, and evergreen contract. By using a cost-plus contract, the buyer agrees to pay all the seller's costs. Some cost-plus contracts provide for payment of both a management fee and a profit, which can be fixed or tied to various productivity and cost reduction incentives. In addition, a base price plus escalation contract uses different components of the price escalate as a fiinction of changing economic conditions or indices.42 At last, an evergreen contract allows the price to be renegotiated at predetermined intervals, usually one year. It may also contain provisions for price adjustments between renegotiations. Table 8 presents the distribution of the contract types, along with their average durations. Most of the contracts in the CTRD are designed as the base price plus escalation contract. Among the contract types, fixed-price contracts have the shortest average duration while cost-plus contracts have the longest one. Table 8 Contract Duration by Pricing Provision: Means and Standard Deviations m . -‘\ ‘1' ovmmn ' ; e ' Base Price Plus Escalation Fixed-Price 20. 14 Evergreen 6.05 Cost-Plus 2.25 (16.71) . 9.1 1 Market-Price 1.1 1 (949) Unknown or Others 10 16 8'59 ' (1.10) Total Number of Observations 5,835 "2 Joskow (1985, pp. 69) gave specific examples on how base price plus escalation contract ties to the economic indices. 40 THE CHOICE OF CONTRACT DURATION To build a new generating plant using coal, there are various decisions to make (Joskow, 1985). First, the utility has to choose the location of the plant. It can build a plant that closes to the service territory, or build a mine-mouth plant. The utility also has to choose the type of coal the plant will utilize, and design the generating unit's boiler accordingly. Moreover, the utility has to consider how the coal will be transported from the mine to the plant. This section empirically tests the determinants of contract duration under these considerations. Empirical Strategy Joskow (1985, 1987) suggested that asset specificity is an important factor affecting the contract structure of the coal contracts. In his seminal paper, J oskow(1987) examined three types of relationship-specific investments proposed by Williamson (1983), including site specificity, dedicated asset specificity, and physical asset specificity. He found that contract duration of the coal contracts are longer when the relationship-specific investments are more important. Using contracts from the franchising industry and the National Football League, Tang (2009) also argued that expected surplus and uncertainty are the other important determinants of contract duration besides specific investments. His empirical evidence suggested that contract length increases with expected surplus and specific investments. Depending on the relative risk attitude of the buyer and seller, contract length increases with uncertainty 41 when the buyer is less risk averse than the seller, and decreases with the buyer is more risk averse than the seller.43 To apply the above ideas on the coal contracts, different proxies are applied for expected surplus, uncertainty, and specific investments in the empirical analysis. First, I use the mine-mouth plant indicator variable as a proxy for expected surplus. Since a mine-mouth plant is designed in anticipation of taking coals fiom the mine that's located next to the plant, the willingness to pay of a mine-mouth plant to acquire coal from its supplier will be greater than to transport coal fi'om the other plants. The same variable is also used by Joskow (1987) as a measure of site specificity. Similarly, the total distance over a route is also used as a proxy for expected surplus, because a plant is willing to pay more for the supply from a closer mine than the other mines. Second, I use the accumulated number of contracts signed between the same plant and supplier across the sample period as a proxy of uncertainty, because it indicates the familiarity between the contracting parties.44 At last, I use the coal supply region as a proxy for specific investments because the coal quality is more heterogeneous in the West than in the Midwest and the East. Coal suppliers are therefore more likely to exploit the lock-in effect associated with boilers designed to burn coal with specific characteristics in the West than in the Midwest and the East (Joskow 1985, 1987). Joskow (1987) used the same proxy to measure the physical asset specificity. The contract quantity is applied as the other proxy for specific investments because the larger the coal supply is contracted, the more difficult for the buyer to replace supplies when the seller breaches the contract “'3 For more comprehensive review of the contract duration literature, see Guriev and Kvasov (2005) and Tang (2009). ‘4 Empirical results are similar if the interactions between utility and supplier are used instead. 42 in the future. Joskow (1987) used the same proxy as a measure for dedicated asset specificity. Empirical Results To test whether the coal contract duration is affected by expected surplus, uncertainty, and specific investments, I regress contract length on whether the plant is a mine-mouth plant, the total distance of a route, the accumulated number of contracts signed between the same plant and supplier across the sample period, the annual contract quantity and the square of the annual contract quantity, whether the coal production region is in the Midwest or the West, and whether the observation is among the observed initial contracts signed between the same plant and supplier. The quality measures of coal and the year fixed effects are also controlled. Four methods are applied for estimation. First, I use the ordinary least square (OLS) estimation as J oskow (1987). However, as J oskow noticed, the contracts that were not in force during or after 1979 are not observed. Specifically, a contract i signed in year T is observed only if DurationiTZ(l979-T), which results in a sample selection problem that may bias the estimation. Therefore, I also apply the truncation regression as used in Joskow (1987), which accounts for the truncated nature of the sample and estimates accordingly.45 In addition, since contract length is a count variable with a lower bound of zero, while the upper limit of contract '5 For the estimation purpose, the lower bound is set as zero. It thus excludes 264 spot purchases in the sample. Estimates obtained using different lower bounds are similar. 43 length in the sample is not restrictive, poisson regression is another appropriate choice that provides positive fitted value with non-constant marginal effect estimates. The zero- truncated poisson regression is also applied to account for the sample selection problem. Table 9 presents the empirical estimates. The signs of the coefficient estimates are comparable with Joskow (1987) and consistent between different estimation methods. The statistically significant results indicate the coal contract length increases with expected surplus and specific investrnents, and decreases with uncertainty. For example, the poisson regression estimates indicate a mine-mouth plant has 41 percent longer contract duration than the other plants, and one thousand more miles between the plant and supplier decreases the contract length by 13 percent. The results support the hypothesis that contract length increases with expected surplus. In addition, contract duration decreases with uncertainty because when there is one more contract signed between the same plant and supplier, the duration of the contract on average increases by three percent. At last, when the agreed quantity is increased by one trillion Btu's, contract duration extends about two percent. The effect indicates contract duration increases with specific investments, and it diminishes as the quantity increases. The longer contract length in the Midwest and the West relative to the East provides the other evidence supporting the positive relationship between contract duration and specific investments. 44 Table 9: OLS and MLE (Truncated, Poisson, and Zero-Truncated Poisson Regressions): Dependant Variable (Contract Duration) Zero- Variable OLS Truncated Poisson Truncated , . Poisson ..-.- Mine-Mouth Plant 10.312*** 7219*" 0.408*** 0.213“ (=1 if the plant is mine-mouth plant) (1.887) (2.744) (0.088) (0.109) Total Distance ofA Route (1,000 miles) -O.790*** -2.514*** -0.130*** -0. 139*" (0.249) (0.683) (0.033) (0.035) Accumulated Number of Contracts 0.536*** 0804*" 0.031*** 0032*" Signed between the Same Plant and Supplier (0.049) (0.085) (0.004) (0.004) Annual Contract Quantity (trillion Btu's) 0204*" 0406*" 0.022*** 0.021*** (0.011) (0.022) (0.001) (0.001) The Square ofAnnual Contract Quantity -0.853*** -2.354*** -0.133*** -0.130"‘** divided by 1,000 (trillion Btu's) (0.129) (0.229) (0.011) (0.011) Midwest (=1 if the coal production 0.581“ 1.054 0.039 0.064* is in the Midwest) (0.265) (0.648) (0.033) (0.033) West (=1 ifthe coal production 1.126“ 3381*" 0.128” 0170*” is in the West) (0.466) (1.058) (0.053) (0.054) Initial ContractA 1376*" 2123*“ 0092*" 0.093*** (0.188) (0.537) (0.027) (0.027) Percentage of Sulfur of the Coal Shipped -0.627*** -1 356*" -0.065*** -0.073*** (0.115) (0.298) (0.015) (0.015) Percentage of Ash of the Coal Shipped -0.063* -0.112 -0.004 -0.004 (0.033) (0.083) (0.004) (0.004) Percentage of Moisture of the Coal Shipped 0.013 0.097" 0.004* 0.004“ (0.023) (0.047) (0.002) (0.002) Year Fixed Effects YES YES YES YES Total Number of Observations 5,835 5,571 5,835 5,571 R-squared 0.671 0.582 0.675 0.677 Log-likelihood -15222. 169 —l9488.75 -18162.854 Note: A. Initial Contract=1 if the observation is among the initial contracts signed between the same parties during the sample period. The coefl'rcient estimates are not marginal effects. Robust deviations are in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *" significant at 1%. 45 THE CHOICE OF PRICING PROVISION A long-term contract saves the renegotiation cost and induces more efficient specific investments. However, the binding agreement also reduces the flexibility of the contracting parties when facing future contingencies. It is therefore important to apply appropriate pricing provision to reduce the costs of signing a long-term contract while preserving the benefits of such contract. Joskow (1988) argued a mutually satisfactory long-term coal contract should incorporate the pricing provision that can 1) equalize the expected revenues and costs of the coal supply; 2) minimize the incentives for the contracting parties to breach; 3) provide enough flexibility to facilitate efficient adaptations to future contingencies; and 4) guard against the potential holdup problem. In this section, I discuss whether the current pricing provisions used in the coal markets have fulfill the requirements above, and then empirically test the determinants of the provision choice. The Pricing Provisions of the Coal Contracts Fixed Price Contract. A long-term fixed price contract will be agreed only if the expected revenue from the coal supply is greater than the expected cost for the supplier. However, any future contingency can change the costs of both the buyer and seller and drive the market value deviates from the original expectation, provides the incentives for the contracting parties to breach. It is therefore less likely to have a long-term contract using the fixed price provision. 46 Market Price Contract. The market price contract is an opposite pricing provision to the fixed price contract and thus minimizes the incentives for the contracting parties to breach when facing the future contingency. However, how market price is defined in the contract is hardly to be accurate because the heterogeneity of the coal contents across different mines (Joskow, 1985, 1988). Besides, there may not even be a market price of the coal for a mine-mouth plant because it is the monopsony of the mine that provides the coal. Consequently, the market price contract creates the possibility of future haggling and provides less protection for the specific investments in the long-term relationship. Evergreen Contract. The evergreen contract functions similarly with the market price contract but with predetermined renegotiation interval. It therefore suffers the same problem as the market price contract with the vague definition of the market price and creates the possibility of haggling from either the buyer or seller. For example, Carlson (1995) illustrated the case that when different grades of coal escalate at different rates, the buyer will bring the evidence that favors the lower price to the annual renegotiation while the seller will evidence that favors a higher price. Therefore, the evergreen contract may offset the benefits from a long-term contract.46 Cost Plus Contract. The difference between contract prices and market values of coal is the major problem that induces the possibility of breach or haggling. Cost plus contract, on the other hand, provides the incentive for the supplier to stay in the relationship by allowing the price to vary with changes in the cost of producing coal. However, this type of contracts fails to provide adequate incentives for the supplier to ‘6 Guriev and Kvasov (2005) showed that efficient investment can be induced through an evergreen contract which is perpetual and allows unilateral termination with advance notice. However, the definition of the evergreen contract in their context is different from here. 47 supply efficiently. The negotiated price can also deviate from the market price because the production costs of a single mine may fluctuate differently from the market values. (Joskow 1985, 1988). Base Price Escalation Contract. The other pricing provision that tracks the market value of coal is the base price escalation contract. This type of contracts allows the agreed price to adjust with some appropriate price and productivity indices reflecting in changes of the cost and productivity of supplier. It can break down the price into different components and relates each component to different indices." Different from the cost plus contract, base price escalation contracts provide incentives for the supplier to minimize costs because the market price fluctuation is independent of the supplier's production decisions (Joskow, 1985). However, this advantage also implies the indices may not be sensitive to unanticipated changes in the market. The market price can deviate fiom the contract price and creates the possibility for haggling. In addition, some components of the production cost may also be difficult to index. '7 For example, see Joskow (1985). 48 EMPIRICAL RESULTS A provision that enhances the benefit of using a long-term contract should be positively related to the determinants that extends contract duration. From the discussion above, the fixed price contract accounts for the least flexibility for a long term contract. Market price contract and evergreen contract can be applied for a long-term contract when there is less haggling expected between the contracting parties over the definition of market price. Base price escalation contract and cost plus contract, on the other hand, provide the most flexibility and the least possibility of haggling. However, an uncertain environment with more possible unanticipated shocks will reduce the probability for the price escalation contract and cost plus contract being negotiated. Cost plus is also a less likely choice when there are more difficult for the utility/plant to monitor the production efficiency of the supplier. Table 10 presents the empirical results. To examine the determinants that affect the choice over different pricing provisions, I estimate a multinomial logit model and use the same regressors as in the contract duration regression. Since the coefficient estimates of the multinomial logit regression solely indicate the log-odds change between the base category and each category as the regressors change, Table 11 presents the choice between pricing provision pairs in the Appendix. Specifically, Table 11 provides the probability change between any pair of the pricing provisions, indicates which provision will be the more or less likely choice than the alternative after the regressors change. For example, when there are one more contract signed between the same parties, base price escalation contract is the more likely choice than cost plus contract, while evergreen 49 contract is a less likely choice compare to cost plus contract. In addition, only the estimates that are statistically significant in the ten percent level are reported, and the results for provisions that fall out of the five categories discussed above are not presented. Table 10 Multinomial Logit Regression: Dependent Variable (Pricin - Provision) .,-.:,:.-.-,-.» . » . gas . C ,Mariable , ._...Esc ' n , Cost Plus . Evergreen . Market Price . Mine-Mouth Plant (=1 ifthe 1.524 3398*“ -39.349 -36.802 plant is mine-mouth plant) (1.160) (1.290) (0.000) (0.000) Total Distance of A Route 0440"" -0.679 0724*" 0.688 (1,000 miles) (0.125) (0.434) (0.206) (0.419) Accumulated Number of Contracts Signed 0.009 -0.164** 0.068” 0.008 between the Same Plant and Supplier (0.024) (0.087) (0.036) (0.091) Annual Contract Quantity 0031*" 0.094‘" 0.041*** 0.054“ (trillion Btu's) (0.006) (0.014) (0.010) (0.021) The Square of Annual Contract Quantity -0.195"'** -0.630*** -0.301** -0.570"‘ divided by 1000(trillion Btu's) (0.071) (0.151) (0.132) (0.317) Midwest (=1 if the coal production -l.140*** -2.158*** -1.237*** -31.369 is in the Midwest) (0.149) (0.402) (0.249) (0.000) West (=1 if the coal production -0.801*** -0.817 4589*“ -1.070" is in the West) (0.200) (0.539) (0.573) (0.629) Initial ContractA -0103 —0.1 11 0.288 0.144 (0.110) (0.377) (0.179) (0.386) Percentage of Sulfur of the Coal Shipped -0.014 0364*” 0165 -0.633*"' (0.063) (0.104) (0.101) (0.294) Percentage of Ash of the Coal Shipped 0.006 -0.042 0103*" 0.054 (0.019) (0.043) (0.030) (0.056) Percentage of Moisture of the Coal Shipped -0.027*** -0.072*** 0.010 0.015 (0.009) (0.024L M21) (0.029) Year Fixed Effects YES Observations 5,835 Log-pseudolikelihood -4979.177 Pseudo R-griared 0.268 Note: A. Initial Contract=1 if the observation is among the initial contracts signed between the same parties during the sample period. B. Base category is fixed price contract. The coefficient estimates are not marginal effects. Robust standard errors presented in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. 50 The empirical results are consistent with the argument of Masten and Saussier (2000) that specific investments and uncertainty are important to the contract design, and also confirm the importance of expected surplus to the contract type choice. To be specific, cost plus contract is the most likely choice for a mine-mouth site. In most cases, cost plus contract is also the less likely choice when a plant is more far away from its supplier. The results indicate cost plus contract is the preferred choice when there are more expected surplus.48 For the plant and supplier who have traded more frequently thus . with less uncertainty, evergreen contract is the more possible choice while cost plus contract is the less likely choice. In addition, fixed price contract is the least likely choice as one more trillion Btu's contracted. It indicates fixed price contract may not be an appropriate provision when there are more specific investments. Cost plus contract, on the other hand, is the most likely choice when there are more specific investments. However, fixed price contract is a more preferred candidate in most of the cases when the coal production is in the Midwest or the West. According to Joskow (1987), the results may indicate that cost surplus contract is the more possible choice when there are more dedicated asset specificity, while fixed cost contract is the choice when there are more physical asset specificity. In conclusion, cost surplus contract is the preferred choice of pricing provision when there are more expected surplus, uncertainty, and dedicated asset specificity. Evergreen contract is the more possible choice when there is less uncertainty, while fixed cost contract is the likely choice when more physical asset specific investments are required. ‘8 The monitoring problem inherited in the cost plus contract can be the alternative explanation of why such contract is the least likely choice when the plant is far away from its supplier. 51 THE SIMULTANEOUS CHOICE OF CONTRACT DURATION AND PRICING PROVISION Since both contract duration and the choice of pricing provision are affected by the same determinants, a joint analysis is applied to examine whether the simultaneity has affected the above empirical evidence. The estimation results using the seemly unrelated regression (SUR) model are listed in Table 12. The dependent variables include contract length and the dummy variables that indicate whether a specific pricing provision has been used. The independent variables are the same as the previous regressions. As Wooldridge (2002) pointed out, the coefficient estimates fi'om the SUR model are the same as the OLS estimations equation by equation with improved estimation efficiency. However, the contract length regression results are not significantly different from the previous estimation with the consideration of simultaneous pricing provision choice. The effects from expected surplus, uncertainty, and specific investments on contract duration remain statistically significant. Moreover, the SUR model also provides comparable results with the estimates from the multinomial logit model on the pricing provision choice: the probability to use a cost plus contract increases with expected surplus; evergreen contract is the more likely choice with less uncertainty while cost plus contract is the more likely option when there are more uncertainty; and the fixed price contract is the more likely choice when the coal production is in the Midwest or the West where more specific investments are required. In addition, the SUR model also indicates base price escalation contract and cost plus contract are the more possible choice with more dedicated asset specificity, while the fixed price contract is the less possible option. The 52 model also indicates the relationship between expected surplus and the adoption of fixed price contract are unclear, because the probability to use fixed price cost is smaller for a mine-mouth site but the probability also decreases with the total distance of a route. Table 12 Seemly Unrelated Regression: Dependent Variables (Contract Duration ‘ Contract ., Market ‘ FiXed- " Variable Duration . Cost Plus . ‘ Evergeen Price Price Mine-Mouth Plant 10.312*** -0.070 0.149“ 0.039 -0.019 -0.125** (=1 if the plant is (0.982) (0.077) (0.024) (0.041) (0.018) (0.059) mine-mouth plant) Total Distance ofA -0.790*** 0.051*** -0.017*** 0.016 0.003 -0.059"““"' Route (1,000 miles) (0.227) (0.018) (0.006) (0.010) (0.004) (0.014) Accumulated 0.536‘" 0.003 -0.004**"‘ 0003* -0.000 -0.003 Number of (0.040) (0.003) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) Contracts Signed between the Same Plant and Supplier Annual Contract 0204*“ 0002*" 0001*“ 0.001 0.000 -0.003*** Quantity (trillion) (0.009) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) Btu's The Square of 0 020*)”. Annual -0.853*** -0.009*** 0007*" -0.004 -0.002* ‘ Contract Quantity (0 005) divided by (0.087) (0.007) (0.006) (0.004) (0.001) ' 1000(trillion Btu's) Midwest (=1 ifthe 0.581" -0.052*** -0.021*** -0.008 -0.010** 0139*" coal production is in (0.259) (0.020) (0.006) (0.011) (0.005) (0.015) the Midwest) West (=1 if the coal 1.126*"'* 0.043 -0.001 -0.105*** 0.002 0125*“ production is in the (0.340) (0.027) (0.008) (0.014) (0.006) (0.020) West) Initial ContractA 1376*" -0.017 -0.006 0.020" 0.002 0002 (0.199) (0.016) (0.005) (0.008) (0.004) (0.012) Percentage of Sulfur -0.627""“* 0.010 0012*” -0.008"‘ -0.004* 0.003 of the Coal Shipped (0.103) (0.008) (0.002) (0.004) (0.002) (0.006) Percentage of Ash -0.063*"' 0008*" -0.001 -0.006*"‘* 0.001 0.001 of the Coal Shipped (0.031) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) @001) (0.002) 53 Table 12 (cont’d) Percentage of 0.013 -0.004*** -0.001 -0.000 0.000 0004*" Moisture of the Coal (0.016) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) Shipped Year Fixed Effects YES YES YES YES YES YES Observations 5,835 5,835 5,835 5,835 5,835 5,835 R-squared 0.67 0.22 0.18 0.23 0.10 0.32 Note: A. Initial Contract=l if the observation is among the initial contracts signed between the same parties during the sample period. To check the simultaneity between the regressions, Table 13 presents the correlation matrix of residuals from the SUR estimation. The results show the residuals from the contract length regression are not significantly correlated with the unexplained variations from the pricing provision regressions. Table 13 also shows the errors from different pricing provision regressions are not significantly correlated with each other, except the substitutions between base price escalation contract and the rest contract types. At last, the Breusch-Pagan test can not reject the existence of simultaneity. Table 13 Correlation Matrix of Residuals from the Seemly Unrelated Regression Fixed Base Price Market Cost Duration Price Escalation Price Plus Evergreen Duration 1.000 Fixed Price -0.147 1.000 Base Price Escalation -0.004 -0.539 1.000 Market Price 0.014 -0.058 -0. 147 1.000 Cost Plus 0.087 -0.014 -0.259 -0.011 1.000 Evergreen 0.050 -0.133 -0.349 -0.033 -0.023 1.000 CONCLUSION This paper extends the seminal paper of Joskow (1987) by examining how contract duration is affected by expected surplus and uncertainty, in additional to his focus on specific investments. The empirical evidence shows contract duration increases with expected surplus and specific investments, and decreases with uncertainty. The results are consistent with Tang (2009). Moreover, this paper also looks at the choice of pricing provision in the coal market. The empirical results indicate a cost plus contract is the more likely choice when there are more expected surplus. The estimates also Show that evergreen contract is the more likely choice when less uncertainty is presented while cost plus contract is the more likely option when more uncertainty exists between the contracting parties. The specific investment is also important for the choice of contract type, where cost plus contract is the more possible choice when there are more dedicated asset specificity, and fixed cost contract is the likely choice when there are more physical asset specificity. While the simultaneous estimation confirms the above findings, the empirical test can not reject the existence of simultaneity between the choice of contract duration and pricing provision. The result indicates the other estimation techniques may be needed to deal with the simultaneous choice problem. There are two potential solutions to address the concern. First, an instrumental variable regression can be applied to address the simultaneity as Crocker and Masten (1991). However, appropriate sets of instrumental variables are necessary for this estimation method. In addition, since contract duration is a count variable and the choice of pricing provision is a discrete choice variable, the 55 nonlinear simultaneous estimation method is the other choice instead of the SUR model. While this paper confirms the simultaneity between the choice of contract duration and pricing provision choice does not significantly affect the results, it will be worthwhile to see the future research exploring how the simultaneity will affect the coal contract design nonlinearly. 56 REFERENCES Bandiera, Oriana. "Contract Duration and Investment Incentives: Evidence from Land Tenancy Agreements," Journal of the European Economic Association, 2007, 5(5), pp. 953-86. Brickley, James A.; Misra Sanjog; and Van Horn, R. Lawrence. "Contract Duration: Evidence fiom Franchising," The Journal of Law and Economics, 2006, 49(1), pp. 1 73-96. Carlson, Kenneth E. "Fossil Fuels," Power Plant Engineering edited by Larry Drbal and Kayla Westra, 1996, Springer Science+Business Media Inc., pp71-123. Cheung, Steven N.S. "Transaction Costs, Risk Aversion, and the Choice of Contractual Arrangements," The Journal of Law and Economics, 1969, 12(1), pp. 23-42. Chiappori, Pierre-Andre and Salanié, Bernard. "Testing Contract Theory: a Survey of Some Recent Work," CESifo Working Paper Series No. 738, 2002, SSRN: http://ssm.com/abstract=3 1 8780 Crocker, Keith J. "Regulatory Issues with Vertically Disintegrated Public Utilities: A Transaction Cost Analysis," in John Groenewegen (eds), Transaction Cost Economics and Beyond, 1996, pp. 85-103, Kluwer Academic Publishers. --------- . and Masten, Scott E. "Mitigating Contractual Hazards: Unilateral Options and Contract Length," RAND Journal of Economics, 1988, 19(3), pp. 327-43. --------- . and Masten, Scott E. "Pretia ex Machina? Prices and Process in Long-Term Contracts," Journal of Law and Economics, 1991 , 34(1), pp. 69-99. --------- . and Reynolds, Kenneth J. "The Efficiency of Incomplete Contracts: An Empirical Analysis of Air Force Engine Procurement," RAND Journal of Economics, 1993, 24(1), pp. 126--46. Guriev, Sergei and Kvasov, Dmitriy. "Contracting on Time," American Economic Review, 2005, 95(5), pp. 1369-85. 57 J oskow, Paul L. "Vertical Integration and Long-Terrn Contracts: The Case of Coal- Burning Electric Generating Plants," Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 1985, 1(1), pp. 33-80. --------- . "Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments: Empirical Evidence from Coal Markets," American Economic Review, 1987, 77(1), pp. 168-85. --------- . "Price Adjustment in Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Coal," Journal of Law and Economics, 1988, 31(1), pp. 47-83. Leffler Keith B. and Rucker Randal R. "Transaction Costs and the Efficient Organization of Production: A Study of Timber-Harvesting Contracts," Journal of Political Economy, 99(5), 1060-87. Masten, Scott E. "Contractual Choice," in B. Boukaert and G. De Geest (eds.), Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Vol. III, The Regulation of Contracts, 2000, pp. 25-45. Edward Elgar Publishing. --------- . and Saussier, Stephane. "Econometrics of Contracts: An Assessment of Developments in the Empirical Literature on Contracting," Revue d'Economie Industrielle, 2000, 92, pp. 215-36. Tang, Meng-Chi. "Contract Length: Expected Surplus, Uncertainty, and Specific Investments," 2009, Michigan State University Working Paper. Wallace, Frederick H. "The Effects of Shock Size and Type on Labor-Contract Duration," Journal of Labor Economics, 2001, 19(3), pp. 658-81. Williamson, Oliver E. "Credible Commitments: Using Hostages to Support Exchange," American Economic Review, 1983, 73, pp. 519-40. Wooldridge, Jeffery. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, 2002 Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press. 58 CHAPTER III THE EFFECT OF AN AGENT’S EXPERIENCE ON NATIONAL FOOTBALL LEAGUE CONTRACT STRUCTURE. “Hiring an agent who has the most experience or who has represented the most number of players is not necessarily the best choice. There are more than 750 certified agents with varying degrees of experience and numbers of clients. ‘Just because an agent is less experienced or works at a smaller firm does not necessarily mean he or she can ’t provide the same level of service or expertise in contract negotiations, ’ Levin said. ” http://wwwnflplayers.com/user/content.aspx?fmid=l78&lmid=443&pid=2557&type=n&weigh=443,0,2557,n (March 16, 2009) INTRODUCTION The above quote on the National Football League Players Association (NF LPA) website indicates that a player’s best choice in terms of representation may not be the agent with the most experience. Mark Levin, the NFLPA’S Director of Salary Cap and Agent Administration, clearly states in the quote above that an agent’s expertise in contract negotiations is not strictly based on the agent’s experience level. He also implies that there are other services, besides contract negotiations, that are provided by an agent which are important for the player to consider when choosing representation. While this paper cannot directly address the question of whether a player is better off by selecting an agent with more experience in contract negotiations, it is the first research we are aware of that empirically tests whether an agent’s experience affects contract structure and contract negotiations. Specifically, this paper estimates how an agent’s experience ' This is a joint work with Mike Conlin and Joe Orsini. For providing the contract data, we are indebted to Michael Duberstein and Mark Levin of the National Football League Players Association. We are also grateful to Mark Levin for providing the agent certification information and invaluable information on the agent’s roll in contract negotiations. Finally, we thank Jeffery Wooldridge and Stacy Dickert-Conlin for their comments, insights and suggestions. 59 affects contract length, how long the negotiations last and whether the contract includes an incentive clause. We use whether an agent is certified by the NFLPA and how long ago an agent obtained the certification as proxies for agent experience. Using contract information on 1,872 players drafted prior to the implementation of NFL salary cap in 1993 and on 1,782 players drafted after its implementation, we find that experienced agents are more likely to negotiate shorter contracts and negotiations are more likely to last past the start of the NFL team’s training camp.49 One explanation for these empirical results is that experienced agents are better informed in terms of the tradeoffs associated with contract duration and missing the start of training camp due to protracted negotiations. For example, experienced agents may realize that while they would be able to get a larger signing bonus if they agree to a contract of longer duration, a longer duration would delay a perhaps sizable increase in salary associated with the player’s subsequent contract.50 Perhaps experienced agents also better understand the cost to the team of a player missing the start of training camp and this cost induces the team to make a more lucrative contract offer after training camp starts.“ (See Conlin 1999 and Conlin & Emerson 2003 for a more detailed discussion of these issues.) Our ‘9 Leeds & Kowalewski (2001) and Larsen, F enn & Spenner (2006) address how the salary cap and free agency afl‘ect player compensation and the competitive balance within the NFL. 50 All else equal, drafted players prefer contracts of shorter duration because they can generally expect to receive a much higher yearly salary in their subsequent contracts if they perform well. The increase in pay between the last year of one contract and the first year of the next contract tends to be greater than the increase in base salary between two years covered under the same contract. As the NFL Player's Association puts it in the 1991 edition of On the Sidelines, “Historically, career earnings have been larger when contract lengths have been shorter... rookies with two-year packages... have done better than entering players with longer deals.” 5' The December 1991 edition of the National Football League Players Association’s (NF LPA’s) publication, 0n the sidelines: an annual economic analysis of the national football league prepared for members of the NFL Players Association, states: “[W]hen a contract is signed has a major impact on what gets signed. For draftees especially, early deals as a rule produce numbers not only below the final averages in a round, but in many cases also under averages from the previous season.” 60 results also suggest that, prior to the NFL salary cap, experienced agents are more likely to negotiate a contract that includes an incentive clause. While the empirical results presented in this paper provide evidence that experienced agents are more likely to negotiate shorter contracts that contain an incentive clause and reach contractual agreement after a longer negotiation period, this does not imply that a player is better off selecting a more experienced agent or that experienced agents negotiate superior contractual terms. As Mark Levin mentions, negotiating contractual terms is just one service an agent provides the player. In addition, we do not have information on how fees vary across agents.52 It may be the case that more experienced agents charge higher fees or that their fee structure differs from 53 What this paper does demonstrate is that there are systematic inexperienced agents. differences in contract structure and how quickly contractual terms are reached when players are represented by an experienced compared to an inexperienced agent. 52 See Sobel (1993) and Dai, Lewis & Lopomo (2006) for two principal-agent models with interesting implications for how the structure of the agent’s compensation should vary as a function of the agent’s growledge. 61 DATA AND SUMMARY STATISTICS The NFL conducts a draft in late April, during which players from the collegiate level are selected by a specific team. All teams are given a draft pick in each round and the order of the picks is based on how the team performed in the prior season. When a player is drafted by a particular team, that team has exclusive rights which prevent other NFL teams from negotiating with that player — unless the other NFL team trades for the player’s rights. In early July, drafted players who have reached contractual agreements attend their team's training camp. At training camp, players improve their conditioning, learn their team’s plays and compete against other NFL teams in exhibition games. Players who have not signed a contract cannot attend training camp. Ahnost all players Sign contracts before the regular season begins, in late August or early September. Our data consist of contract information for drafted players from two time periods: 1986 through 1991 and 2001 through 2007. The earlier time period is prior to a salary cap negotiated between the NFL and the NFLPA in their 1993 Collective Bargaining Agreement (CBA). While a number of changes have occurred in the CBA post-1993, the basic structure of the salary cap has not. The most significant changes for our analysis are the restriction in 2006 on the maximum length of a drafted player’s contract and the changes in what constitutes a restricted free agent, an unrestricted free agent and a “franchised” player.54 Some minor changes have also occurred in the draft. Specifically, 5" Section 5 of Article XVII of the 2006 CBA states: “Tire initial Players Contract of a Rookie, including any Club option, may not exceed four years in length, except that the initial Player Contract of a Rookie drafied with a selection in the first half of the first round (e. g., the first sixteen of thirty-two selections in the 2006 Draft), including any Club option, may not exceed six years in length, and the initial Player Contract of a Rookie drafted with a selection in the second half of the first round, including any Club option, may not exceed five years in length.” Articles XVIII and XIX of the CBA provide the details on restricted free agents, unrestricted free agents and the “franchise” designation. 62 the number of NFL teams (each of which has drafting rights) has increased from 28 in 1985 to 32 in 2007, the number of rounds in a draft has decreased fi'om twelve in the earlier time period to seven in the later time period and 32 “compensatory picks” were awarded (each year from 2001 thru 2007) to teams that lost players due to free agency. Most players hire an agent or multiple agents prior to the draft to negotiate their contract. While some players represent themselves or have a family member/friend negotiate the contract, most players hire professional agents who specialize in representing professional athletes. In 2003, the NFLPA restricted the agent’s compensation to be a maximum of three percent of the contract’s value but this rate is 55 In addition to this compensation, agents often receive compensation for negotiable. providing additional services to the player such as negotiating promotional deals. Once a player is drafted, a representative of the drafting team negotiates contract terms with the player’s agent/representative. These negotiations ahnost always result in a contractual agreement where the player signs what is often termed a “Standard Form Contract”. (See Appendix C of the 2006 CBA for a sample of this contract.) Besides the amount of the signing bonus, base salaries, contract length, and (on occasion) incentive clauses, the contracts signed by players drafted prior to the salary cap were largely standardized. Those contracts signed in the 2001 through 2007 drafts were less standard because the structure of the contract influenced how much the player’s compensation counted against the salary cap. For example, these contracts often contained a wide variety of incentive 55 A player can also compensate his representative on a fixed fee or an hourly basis. However, most agents’ compensation is a function of the contract terms (i.e., a contingent fee). 63 clauses because the “value” of an incentive clause for salary cap purposes depends on whether the incentive clause was “likely to be earned”.56 Our dataset contains contract information, the player’s college and the date of agent certification provided by the NFLPA. The NFL provided training camp starting dates for the different teams while team information (including win-loss records, attendance, stadium capacity and head coach tenure) was collected from the NFL Record and Fact Books. Finally, information on whether the drafi picks attended a Division IA college football program was collected from the Official National Collegiate Athletic Association College Football Records Books. Table 14: Descriptive Statistics (Means and Standard Deviations) 1986-1991 2001-2007 . Drafts :2 : Drafts i Contract Duration (years) 2. 736 3.809 (0.805) (1.024) Rookie Training Camp (=1 if sign after start of 0.504 0.409 Training Camp, 0 otherwise) (0.500) (0.492) Incentive Clause (=1 if incentive clause, 0 0.033 0.262 otherwise) (0.179) (0.440) Agent Certified Prior (=1 if agent certified prior to 0.334 0.937 Draft, 0 otherwise) (0.472) (0.244) Number of Years Agent Certified prior to Draft 4.408 13.258 (1.945) (5.656) Agent Ever Certified (=1 if agent was ever 0.426 0.941 certified, 0 otherwise) (0.495) (0.237) Selection Number in Draft 161 128 (95) (74) 5‘ See Section 7 of Article XXIV in the 2006 CBA for a detailed discussion of how incentive clauses are accounted for in salary cap calculations. 64 Table 14 (cont’d) Fraction of Empty Seats in Stadium for Team in 0.182 0.055 Prior Year (0.143) (0.081) Nmnber of Team Wins in Prior Year 7.769 7.877 (2.965) (3.054) College Division (=1 if player competed in Div IA 0.791 0.914 college program, 0 otherwise) (0.407) (0.280) Stadium Capacity (10,000) 6.802 6.971 (0.919) (0.611) Increase in Stadium Capacity from Prior Year 0.067 0.079 (0.251) (0.269) Decrease in Stadium Capacity from Prior Year 0.025 0.042 (0.155) (0.200) Population of Team’s MSA (in 1,000,000) 4.782 5.008 (4.935) (4.955) Tenure of Team’s Head Coach (years) 5.723 3.960 (6.381) (3.045) Total Number of Observations 1,872 1,782 2007. 57 Table 14 contains the variables’ means and standard deviations for the 1,872 draft 65 selections from 1986 through 1991 and for the 1,782 draft selections from 2001 through In terms of contract length, the average for the 1986-91 selections is approximately a year less than for the 2001-07 selections (2.736 years compared to 3.809 years). The primary reason for this difference is that early round draft choices usually sign longer contracts than late round choices and there were five more rounds in the early time period. This also explains why the fraction of draftees from Division IA schools is 57 We have information on all contracts reported to the National Football League Players Association (NF LPA). Approximately 95% of all drafted payers in 1986 thru 1991 reported the contractual terms to the NFLPA and almost 100% reported from the 2001 thru 2007 drafts. much less for the early time period - players from smaller football programs are more likely to be drafted in the later rounds. Draftees in the early time period are also less likely to Sign a contract before the start of training camp and much less likely to have an incentive clause in their contract. The main reason why incentive clauses are more prevalent in the 2001-2007 drafts is because providing compensation in the form of incentive clauses allows teams to better manage their salary cap. In terms of agent certification, Table 1 indicates that a third of the draftees selected in the 1986-1991 drafts were represented by a certified agent while 93.7 percent of the 2001-2007 contracts were negotiated by agents who were certified. For those represented by a certified agent, the average number of years between certification and contract negotiation is 4.41 years for 1986—91 and 13.26 years for 2001-07.58 For the different number of years between certification and contract negotiation, Figure 8 presents the relevant number of 2001-07 contracts. As the figure depicts, the number of years range between 0 and 25 with a concentration between 13 and 19 years. Figure 8 Number of Years Agent Certified Prior to Draft for the 2001-2007 Contracts | l I l I . 58 For players represented by more than one agent, we define the number of years between certification and contract negotiation based on the agent who first became certified. 120 0 . . 0 1n 0 ,_ Years Mont Cortlflod 8 Number of Contact: A a: o o 8 1n 66 EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION AND ESTIMATION We test how an agent's experience/certification affects contract length, whether contractual terms are reached after the start of training camp and whether the contract includes an incentive clause. Because contract length is a count variable that ranges from 1 to 6 years in the early period and from 1 to 7 years in the later period, we estimate a binomial regression model when considering contract length. Specifically, we assume that the conditional mean of the length to be estimated equals np(XiB), where X; contains the set of regressors, p(.) is a probability function estimated by the logit model and n is the maximum contract length”. When considering how the agent’s experience affects whether contractual terms are reached after the start of training camp and whether the contract includes an incentive clause, we estimate probit models since both are binary variables. The binomial regression and probit models are estimated separately for the 1986-91 and 2001-07 data. The set of regressors are the same across models and include team, player, draft and agent characteristics. The team characteristics consist of the fiaction of empty stadium seats in the prior season, number of wins in the prior season, stadium capacity, whether stadium capacity increased or decreased by over 1,000 seats from the prior year, MSA population and head coach tenure.60 The set of regressors also includes team specific indicator variables to control for unobserved, time-invariant team characteristics. The player characteristics include whether the player competed in a Division IA college 59 Since contract length in the sample is a count variable ranging from 1 to 6 or 1 to 7, multiplying the estimated probability function by 6 or 7 guarantees the fitted values for contract length fall within this range. If we use ordinary least squares, it is possible to obtain fitted values of contract length that are negative. Moreover, although count data is often assumed to have Poisson distribution, Poisson regression may produce some fitted values exceeding the upper bound of the sample. 60 Annual MSA population measures are constructed by interpolating and extrapolating population counts from the decennial census. 67 football program and a full complement of player position indicator variables. The player’s selection number in the draft, indicator variables for the round the player was selected in the draft and indicator variables for the year of the draft are also included as regressors. These team, player and draft characteristics control for non-agent factors that are likely to influence contract negotiations and contract structure."l Finally, to test whether an agent’s experience affects contract negotiations/structure, the set of regressors includes whether the agent was certified prior to the contract negotiations. For the 2001- 07 data, we also include the number of years the agent was certified prior to the contract negotiations.62 Table 15 Binomial Regression and Probit Models 1986-1991 Drafts ' Contract Training Incentive _ _ . Duration .Camp Clause _- I Agent Certified Prior (=1 ifagent -0.035** 0.240" 0.368“ 0.059 -0.023 -0.004 certified prior (0.017) (0.068) (0.129) (0.040) (0.181) (0.171) to Drafi) Years Agent is -0.004** 0.013" 0.004 Certified Prior (0.002) (0.006) (0.006) to Draft Selection —0.004** -0.001 -0.017* -0.002* 0.005 -0.003 Number in (0.001) (0.005) (0.010) (0.001) (0.003) (0.004) Draft 6' Tang (2008) uses the same datasets as this paper to test whether expected surplus, uncertainty and specificity of investment affects contract length. He proxies for these three characteristics of the negotiations using many of the same team, player and draft characteristics. 62 From 1986 thru 1991, the benefit an agent derived from being certified by the NFLPA was much less than in the later years. In recent years, the NFLPA has provided much more assistance to players deciding which agent to select and this has increased the agent’s benefit of being certified by the NFLPA. As NFLPA Director of Salary Cap and Agent Administration Mark Levin states: “We have files on every agent. We can tell a player what contracts an agent has negotiated, who they represent, what fees they charge and most importantly, whether the Committee on Agent Regulation and Discipline has ever taken action against the agent.” h This results in far fewer agents being certified and makes years since certification a much less reliable proxy for agent experience in the early time period. Therefore, we did not include years since certification as a regressor when estimating the models using this early time period. 68 Table 15 (cont’d) Fraction of Empty Seats in Stadium for 0.102 0.995" 0.389 -0.217 -0.444 0.945 Team in Prior (0.131) (0.505) (1.046) (0.184) (0.855) (0.905) Year Number of 0.001 0.026 0.021 -0.007* 0.020 0.001 Team Wins in (0.005) (0.020) (0.041) (0.004) (0.015) (0.016) Prior Year College Division (=1 if player competed in -0.055** 0.029 0.051 -0.026 0.183 0.092 Div IA college (0.019) (0.079) (0.160) (0.031) (0.127) (0.125) Prograln) Stadium -0.069 -0.272 -0.712 0.017 0.197 0.226 Capacity (0.044) (0.176) (0.641) (0.037) (0.176) (0.181) (10,000) Increase in Stadium -0.037 0.285 -0.100** 0.106 -0.039 Capacity from (0.049) (0.185) (0.032) (0.157) (0.166) Prior Year Decrease in Stadium -0.104* -0.320 6.387 -0.050 -0.l44 -0.026 Capacity from (0.057) (0.235) (4.013) (0.039) (0.195) (0.192) Prior Year Population of -0.162** 0.047 -0.803 0.029 -0.246 0.159 Team’s MSA (0.053) (0.176) (0.675) (0.033) (0.173) (0.194) (in 1,000,000) Tenure of 0.013" 0.026" -0.030 0.007 0.005 0.006 Team’s Head (0.003) (0.012) (0.021) (0.004) (0.021) (0.021) Coach (years) Fixed EffectsA YES YES YES YES YES YES R-squared 0.167 0.140 0.191 0.263 0.265 0.184 Log- Likelihood -2,255 -1,115 -200 -2,292 -881 -831 N'm'be’ff 1,872 1,872 1,261 1,770 1,770 1,770 Observatrons Notes: A. Indicator variables include the position, round, team, and year fixed effects. The standard errors in parentheses are robust to arbitrary heteroskedasticity. * Statistically significant at .10 level; ** Statistically significant at .05 level. The SS column denotes whether we can reject the null that the corresponding coefficients in the related and unrelated accident probits are equal. 69 The coefficient estimates associated with the binomial regression and probit models are shown in Table 15. Both before and after the salary cap, these estimates indicate that more experienced agents are likely to agree to shorter contracts and be involved in more protracted contract negotiations.63 For the 1986-91 drafts, experienced agents are also more likely to negotiate contracts that contain incentive clauses.64 For this early period, the marginal effects corresponding to the coefficients associated with having a certified agent indicate that an agent being certified decreases the contract duration by 0.05 years (coefficient of -0.035), increases the probability of signing after the start of training camp by ten percentage points (coefficient of 0.240), and increases the probability of an incentive clause by one percentage point (coefficient of 0.368). As for the 2001-07 drafts, the marginal effects of having an agent certified ten years earlier are to decrease the expected contract duration by 0.07 years and to increase the probability of signing after the start of training camp by five percentage points. However, it has a negligible affect on the probability the contract contains an incentive clause. The coefficient estimates for this later time period also suggest that whether the agent is certified, of which 93.7% are, does not appear to influence when the contract is signed or its structure in a statistically significant manner.65 As for the coefficients associated with the other regressors in the contract duration specification, these are consistent with the results of Tang (2008) who finds that players drafted in the early rounds of the draft, quarterbacks and players from smaller college 63 Because the Houston Texans entered the NFL in 2002 and therefore the prior year variables are missing, the twelve observations of 2002 Houston Texans draft choices are not included in Table 2 regressions (resulting in the number of observations being 1,770 instead of 1,782). The number of observations is less when the dependent variable is incentive clause (1,261 compared to 1,872) because certain team and round indicators are perfect predictors of whether contracts have an incentive clause. 65 For both before and after the salary cap, the qualitative results do not change appreciably if number of drafted players an agent represents in our dataset is used to proxy for agent experience. 70 football programs (Non-Division IA) are likely to Sign longer contracts. Finally, the estimates in Table 15 indicate that while certain team, player and draft characteristics included as regressors influence contract length, they do not appreciably affect when the contract is signed and whether the contract contains an incentive clause. 71 CONCLUSION This paper uses contract information for football players drafted into the NFL to test whether the experience level of the player’s agent influences the contract structure and negotiation process. We find that experienced agents are more likely to negotiate shorter contracts that contain incentive clauses and be involved in more protracted contract negotiations. While our results indicate that the contract structure varies systematically with the experience level of the player’s agent, we are unable to infer from these results whether it is beneficial for the player to hire an experienced agent. One factor that directly influences the player’s optimal agent choice is the agent’s compensation. While we do not have information on this compensation, we believe research focusing on how this compensation varies with agent and player characteristics would provide valuable insight into this principal-agent relationship. In addition, this research could test the theoretical predictions of the principal-agent models where the knowledge of the agent varies. 72 REFERENCES Collective Bargaining Agreement (CBA): between The NFL Management Council and The NFL Players Association, March 8, 2006. http://www.nflplayers.com/user/template.aspx?frnid=l 81 &lmid=622&pid=0&typ g=_l Dai, Chifeng, Tracy R. Lewis and Giuseppe Lopomo. “Delegating Management to Experts”, Rand Journal of Economics, 37(3): 503-520, Autumn 2006. Conlin, Michael. “Empirical Test of a Separating Equilibrium in National Football League Contract Negotiations”, Rand Journal of Economics, 30(2): 289-304, Summer 1999. Conlin, Michael and Patrick Emerson. “Multi-Dimensional Separating Equilibrium and Moral Hazard: An Empirical Study of National Football League Contract Negotiations”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(3): 760-765, August 2003. Larsen, Andrew, Aju J. Penn and Erin Learme Spenner. “The Impact of Free Agency and the Salary Cap on Competitive Balance in the National Football League”, Journal of Sports Economics, 7(4): 374-390, November 2006. Leeds, Michael A. and Sandra Kowalewski. “Winner Take All in the NFL: The Effect of the Salary Cap and Free Agency on the Compensation of Skill Position Players”, Journal of Sports Economics, 2(3): 244-256, August 2001. Sobel, J oel. “Information Control in the Principal-Agent Problem”, International Economic Review, 34(2): 259-269, May 1993 Tang, Meng-Chi. “Contract Length: Expected Surplus, Uncertainty, and Specific Investments”, Michigan State University working paper, 2008. Wooldridge, Jeffery. "Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, ” Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press, 2002. 73 + + + + + vommEm :80 05.8 Rams—2 .«o owfiaoocom 3&5 =80 ofimo :3. mo owsgouom 883m :80 05 no .525 we owfieoonom 9.63 2: 5 mm 853.95 Eco 05.x TV ~83 @8322 on: E a eouozuoa 38 05.: TV “8322 9.3m 85:: 3.3530 82:00 3:53 Saddam was “SE 25% 2: e853 Rama £8550 mo 55:52 poise—33‘ 30:8 25.: 83M < no 8535 :38. O53 5.85-qu a can on; .uv ago 582852 out; out; 8va Sofia—2 succumbing SE 8x32 :anmozm 2.5 280 5999m— 2:.”— $00 82.5 nuocmco>m ocean—2 secs—mumm— BEL 8am 35 ~80 norm—50mm 035 Sam ea... eon...— 233$ $3358? 05 82: 86:0 383 $2 2: mm 5630a moh N. 63882? 2: ~85 oomoao box: 208 2: mm comma/ca no... IL Tue: awed 3.52532 .3 185858 FEE aegis—h ”53.5 5952. 33:0 2:. 2 03.; EGZm—mmdw 74 will [laillllllll iii! lilillliliiiililiiillleS 3 1293 03063 0804