TWO \NDMDUAUSTIC APPROACHES TO AN ANALYSB 0F " DEVELOPMENT \N \ND\A Dissertation for the Degree of Ph. D. MlCH\GAN STATE UNNERSH‘Y MASUMA DOWME 1976 This is to certify that the thesis entitled AN ANALYSIS OF TWO INDIVIDUALISTIC APPROACHES TO DEVELOPMENT IN INDIA presented by Masuma Downie has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph. D. degree in Secondary Education ‘ and Curriculum NNNNNN \Majg professor WV Date //- /.2 '72 07639 ABSTRACT AN ANALYSIS OF TWO INDIVIDUALISTIC APPROACHES TO DEVELOPMENT IN INDIA by Masuma Downie This study examined two educational programs in which social change and development were explained as the result of changes in particular individual propensities, motives and values. The major purpose in presenting the two case studies was their status as individualistic psychological approaches within social science. A survey of individualistic psychological approaches in the context of social change theories was also provided. Nithin social science the adoption of individualistic approaches in explanation of development and social change was a reaction to extreme forms of positivism in which the collective and the normative served as the focus of analysis. In the use of positivistic approaches the general concern of writers has been to show the variety of ways in which institutions fit together to main- tain Society in a state of equilibrium. The positivist emphasis is on a smoothly functioning social system in which individuals perform roles prescribed by the social system. The survival of society is Masuma Downie taken as a given and the ultimate end of behavior and the function of institutions is to contribute to the maintenance of the system. To correct the over-emphasis on institutions and institu- tionalized role behavior, social scientists using individualistic psychological approaches attempted to bring men back into the analysis of social change. Factors which were perceived to determine action were not rules nor social laws but the exercise of individual choice and motives in action. Specific individual propensities, dispositions, values, desires, and motives became the focus of analysis. Within the literature on change and development theoretical priority was assigned to psychological configurations and individual attributes. The concern was to determine the effect of Specific motives and values on particular goals of development--to isolate and identify motives and values as the causative elements which either enhance or retard social change. Two educational programs from India were described, then analyzed for theoretical pre-suppositions, the adequacy of empirical data, and policy consequences. One was a program of psychological education undertaken by David C. McClelland and his colleagues to motivate economic achievement in a group of businessmen and thereby guarantee economic growth in society. .The other was the Scheme of Basic Education devised by Mahatma Gandhi to transform individual values and reconstruct Indian society. In the analysis of the two cases a number of points of con- vergence and divergence became evident. Both programs provide Masuma Downie illustrations of individualistic approaches in explanation of social change by first advocating change at the individual level. Particular individual values, interests, and motives were credited with inhibiting or enhancing change. Through specific educational inputs individual commitment to a particular set of values was sought. Change on the part of the individual from one value set to another was perceived to guarantee social change. However, in spite of certain similarities in pre-suppositions, analysis revealed a number of points of divergence between McClelland and Gandhi--in the types of values emphasized, the kinds of education used, in the focus on different groups of individuals. Most impor- tantly, they differed markedly in their perceptions of the goals of social change. McClelland's educational program for social change incorporated Western assumptions and orientations concerning the nature of change, its direction, and the ways it could be achieved. Moreover, he held that individual self-interest in the pursuit of greater entrepre- neurial success and the ends of economic development coalesce. McClelland's theory assumes a harmony of interest between individual self-interest and the common good. Gandhi's perceptions of social change were diametrically opposed to McClelland's. The difference was not just in degree and rate of change, or levels of development, but in the kind of develop- ment he perceived. The indicators were neither growth, modernization, nor industrialization. Gandhi's concerns were with divising ways and means for solving the overriding and urgent problems facing Indian Masuma Downie society. Gandhi sought to create a non-violent and non-exploitative society--a society in which each man would seek Truth through the ideal means of Non-violence and Love. These values were viewed as inherent in human nature and could be realized through training. It was their pursuit which could lead to the all-round development of individual personality. Through determined persuasion and conver- sion and by changing men's inner environment exploitation and violence could be overcome. Social change could be obtained through the transformation of values, since the highest values required service of society. Inner progress and service of society were con- ceived to be the same. Both in his private and public life, Gandhi maintained a drive toward consistency between the ideal and the real and a similar commonality of interests between individual values and the common good was at the core of Basic Education. At the level of theoretical abstraction and generalization, however, both educational programs show similarity in certain assump— tions concerning the individual and society. Implicit in both, at the individual level, was a denial of variation in action--that is, all individuals could be brought to value ends advocated by the pro- tagonists. Furthermore, through specific educational programs, indi- vidual conformity to specific goals could be achieved. At the societal level, the multiplicity of processes involved in social change were considered to be directed toward the attainment of common, uniting ends and conflicting or contradictory ends were ignored. In both cases, education was identified as the means by which individuals would be transformed and social change guaranteed. AN ANALYSIS OF TWO INDIVIDUALISTIC APPROACHES TO DEVELOPMENT IN INDIA By Masuma Downie A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY College of Education 1976 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The ritual of acknowledgment of debts of gratitude to individuals who have contributed in their own special way to the completion of this study is a useful and important devise and I endorse it wholeheartedly. I have always admired Marvin Grandstaff's perceptive analysis and understanding of his own culture and above all his objectivity mixed with a talent to enjoy it aesthetically. As the chairman of my committee, I could not have asked for nor received greater support and advice always laced with candor. Ted Hard's persistent and incisive questionings and probings required that I be prepared to defend every aspect of an issue; and he kept me busy in the search for better ones. My debts to Joe Spielberg will continue to grow the longer I am associated with him. A number of terms and concepts used in this study are drawn from unpublished lectures of Professor Spielberg, and I must offer my appreciation to him on this and many other points. His critical analysis and not quite total satisfaction with a piece of writing leaves me with the realization that it is still an unfinished task. Thanks are also due to Dr. Cole Brembeck for his helpful and timely suggestions through the course of my writing, and to ii Dr. Keith Anderson for his willingness to serve on my doctoral committee in Dr. Brembeck's absence. Final thanks to my husband Richard, who has provided a source of strength in letting me pursue my own intellectual development. iii Chapter I. II. III. I\I. TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION Statement of the Problem . . Significance and Purpose of the Study. Methodological Limitations . Organization of the Dissertation INDIVIDUALISTIC PSYCHOLOGICAL APPROACHES IN THE CONTEXT OF SOCIAL CHANGE THEORY. . . Introduction Positivistic Approaches Within Social Science Individualistic Psychological Approaches in Explanation of Social Change . . Analysis of Individualistic Psychological Approaches . MCCLELLAND'S TRAINING PROGRAM TO MODIFY INDIVIDUAL ACHIEVEMENT MOTIVATION AND GUARANTEE SOCIAL CHANGE General Characteristics of McClelland's Theoretical Model . . The Experimental Context . Implementation of Educational Program for n Achievement . . Assessment and Outcome of the Training in Motivation Program . . . . . . . ANALYSIS AND EVALUATION OF MCCLELLAND' S TRAINING PROGRAM IN NEED ACHIEVEMENT . . Analysis of Theoretical Presuppositions . . . . Adequacy of Data and Its Empirical Validity. . . . Policy Implications . . . . . GANDHIAN SCHEME OF BASIC EDUCATION TO TRANSFORM INDIVIDUALS AND RECONSTRUCT SOCIETY . Introduction -Goals, ObjectiVes, and Principles of Basic Education : Implementation of Basic Education . Assessment and Outcomes of Basic Education iv 23 23 24 29 33 43 43 47 49 54 62 62 71 78 Chapter Page VI. ANALYSIS AND EVALUATION OF THE GANDHIAN PHILOSOPHY OF SOCIAL CHANGE IN ACTION . . . . . . . 104 Some General Characteristics of Gandhian Ideology . . 104 Nature of Man . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107 Nature of Society. . . . 110 Some Outcomes and Results of the Gandhian Ideas in Practice . . . . . ll4 Secular Aspects of Gandhian Ideas and the Social and Economic Realities . . . . . . . . . . 125 VII. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS . . . . . . . . . . I30 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137 Concluding Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . l4l BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 Chapter Page VI. ANALYSIS AND EVALUATION OF THE GANDHIAN PHILOSOPHY OF SOCIAL CHANGE IN ACTION . . . . . . 104 Some General Characteristics of Gandhian Ideology . . 104 Nature of Man . . . . . . . . . . . . . 107 Nature of Society. . . . 110 Some Outcomes and Results of the Gandhian Ideas in Practice . . . . . 114 Secular Aspects of Gandhian Ideas and the Social and Economic Realities . . . . . . . . . . 125 VII. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS . . . . . . . . . . I30 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137 Concluding Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . l4l BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION Statement of the Problem A persistent problem in the literature on social theory and social policy is that of change--how does it come about, how can it be fostered, how can it be understood, and so on. Generally, social scientists and educationists attempting to understand, explain and implement social change adopt one of several approaches. Depending upon research interest, ideology and the theoretical leanings of the writers, relative importance has been given to one or another order of variables--economic, cultural, political, ecological, or psycho- logical--as elements that produce social change. In this study an attempt will be made to examine one such approach--one which, on a theoretical and empirical level, undertakes to explain social change and development by reference to individual psychological states. The focus of what is here termed as the "psychological" or "individualistic" approach is on the individual actor in a particular context: his needs, knowledge, motivation, values, and desires.1 Writers using the psychological approach are 1The theories to be discussed here are those that take the psychology of individuals as main determinants of change. This appranh will be termed either "psychological" or "individualistic." (See Brodbeck, 1954, 1958, 1968; Beattie, 1964; Frank, 1967; and White, 1949, 1973. Further explanation of the concept will be given in Chapter II.) I concerned to identify psychological states (or external influences upon psychological states) to which cause of, or functional correla- tion to, behavior can be ascribed. Although all theorists recognize that the full range of identifiable variables is interactive--individual psychology inter- acts with economic structures, etc.--most theories of change can be seen to give priority to some particular set of variables. This is especially so when the problems of initiating change or of describing ultimate change outcomes are examined. The difficult problem of laying out a taxonomy of theories will not be undertaken other than a stipulative identification of psychological theories as one major and influential theoretical position. Whether there are stable motives in individuals, or whether individual motives, desires and attitudes can be manipulated is not the subject of this study. Those issues are the specific concern of experimental psychologists, and their resolution is open to controversy as evidenced in the literature in that special branch of social science. The concern here is with programs of social change and the explanations provided for change which are based upon psychological presuppositions concerning individual behaviors and action.2 2This is in contrast to explanations that give priority to material conditions and those which emphasize social and political structures. This study will not compare individual psychological (ideological) approaches with structural and materialist perspectives, although any analysis and critique is, in a sense, an implicit com- parison. To suggest inadequacies in one line of explanation contains the supposition that some other line is more powerful or parsimonious. It is the general view of the author that materialist explanations of social change are (usually) superior to ideological ones (see Harris: 1968) but the present work attempts only the analysis and criticism of two individual psychological cases. The specific concern in this study is to examine, through literature on educational programs and practices of development, the psychological and individualistic presuppositions of change programs, and the strengths and weaknesses of such programs in obtaining and explaining social change. Such programs can be loosely divided into two general types. One, the individualistic psychological perspective to social change implies that change on the conative, affective, and cognative dimensions of the personality of the actor is necessary. The premise is that individual attributes-~motives, desires, and values--are the critical variables, and unless these psychological attributes are changed the possibility of social, economic, and cultural change is remote. Another assumption is that underdevelopment is the result of certain traditional attitudes and beliefs, and only by first changing individual attitudes, motives and desires can development occur. Both premises rest upon the view that individual motives, desires, and values can be manipulated and are vulnerable to every kind of external influence. Changes in motives require personal commitment on the part of each individual. For example, Gandhi, according to Gupta, sought to operationalize his vision of the ideal society essentially through personal virtues. The sources of his collective action (e.g., non-cooperation movement) were derived from the personal commitment of the participants, not by the institutional norms of systemic conformity. In his definition, swaraj comes when one learns to rule oneself. Such swaraj has to be experienced by each man for himself (Gupta, [971:86). Large scale programs of social change and development have been under- taken in India premised on the transformation of individual attitudes, values, and motives. Gandhi visualized a country of "selfless and non-political community service," and Jayaprakash Narayan formulated utopian proposals for the "reconstruction of Indian polity" based on transformation of individual values (Hanson, 1966:260-61). The strategy adopted is to design and implement programs aimed at "the masses," often in the rural areas. The community development program, for example, was "launched with a view to chang- ing the very philosophical basis of rural reconstruction." It attempts: . . . to create a psychological change in the villagers . it aims at inculcating in the villagers new desires, new incentives, new techniques, and a new confidence so that this vast reservoir of human resources may be used for the graying economic development of the country (Desai, 1969: General social uplift and reform at the individual level through the internalizing of specific norms (Gupta, 1971) is the overriding concern and attempts are made to directly try and "prod, inform, teach, exhort, and otherwise manipulate" the individual (Lewis, 1964: 160). The strategy adopted by another group of social scientists is to deduce consequences from some previously established ideal-typical set of attitudes, values, and motives, such as the profit motive or the need for achievement (Singer, 1966). The specific concern of investigators using this approach is to identify individuals who have these characteristics, or who display these latent attributes, in order that such "innovative" or entrepreneurial individuals can become the agents of social change. The assumption made here is that a particular configuration of motives, needs, and desires stand for all time. For example, the notion of profit motive assumes uniformity in individual behaviors. Consequently, in order to bring about social change, certain specific motives within individuals most be fulfilled or permitted to find expression. As a result, some programs of social change undertaken are explicitly based on explaining social change by recourse to individual motives, needs and desires. McClelland suggests, for example, that the need for achievement, one aspect of man's internal state, is responsible for economic development. A society with a generally high level of g_Achievement will produce more energetic entrepreneurs who, in turn produce more rapid economic development (McClelland, 1961: 205). The notion of individual achievement presupposes that given "the will and ability" an individual can rise to any station in life (Turner, 1972:65). Attempts may be made to identify individuals who do not display the particular motives, and programs of change undertaken to overcome these deficiencies, but such programs place "the burden of change? on the individual (Turner, 1972:208). .However, in the context of developing countries, the focus is on individual entrepreneurs and innovators, that is, individuals who display characteristics which are considered "modern" and these are the prerequisites for social change and development (Inkeles, 1966; Lerner, 1958; Rogers, 1968). The strategy followed in this case is first to devise, under controlled situations, tests and measures to identify particular motives and desires; achievement is measured by means of thematic apperception tests, or in the case of country comparisons, by levels of "achievement imagery" in children's stories, plays, novels, etc. Such variables are, in turn, related to economic growth measured by "electricity consumption" (Blaugh, 1972:85-87) or some other economic indicator. In the educational program undertaken by McClelland, for example, focus is on an identifiable group of businessmen and inno- vators who are considered potential agents of economic development and social change, and attempt is made to promote in such individuals a striving for success and a strong desire to excel, which will then contribute to the goals of economic development and growth. The orientation of the individualistic and psychological approach is to assign theoretical priority to psychological configura- tions--needs, knbwledge, motivation, values, and desires--of those involved in implementing and furthering social change. In this study the concern is with examining the extent to WhTCIl psychological and individualistic assumptions underlie programs and [oractices in education and development. Significance and Purpose of the Study The role and function of education as an instrument and tool for-'thersocial good of the whole society and for the development and creation of desirable traits and characteristics and habits in ind-i Vi dual personality has always been a recognized fact of human SOCIBI life. (One needs only to note the role of education in Plato's Republic.) Education has often been viewed as an instrument for cultural continuity, through personality development, accumulation and transmission of knowledge, and maintenance of social solidarity. The functions of education were considered to be conservation of values, social institutions, traditions, and morality. In brief education was for conformity. The combination of technological breakthroughs, de- colonization, the two world wars, plus the growth in the sciences, however, led to a growing interest in progress and change. On the one hand science was utilized for industrial growth and development, and on the other hand attempts to change institutions and individual personality, attitudes and values, and, consequently, to create changes in the social and cultural realms, were undertaken by social scientists and educationists interested in social change. The balance of attention shifted from the conservative func- tion of education to its capacity for the change and transformation of individuals and society through education (Aran, Eisenstadt and Adler, 1972; Gezi, 1971). Social scientists were called in to assist policy makers in implementing directed change. Discussing the role of social science in policy, Myrdal states that historically, knowledge and the uses of knowledge have been Opportunistically distorted (Myrdal, 1970). In the colonial era, approaches to, and conceptions of, underdeveloped countries were from Western views of man. These were undergirded by concepts and theories of social science which sup- posedly provided scientific validity to explanations of change or lack of it. What seemed most important about other countries were the ways in which they differed from Western society. Depending upon the particular program of change--educationa1, agricultural, or industria1--people in colonized countries were seen to be idle, inefficient, lacking in ambition and in a competitive enterprising spirit, fatalistic and lacking in rationality. Social relations, beliefs, values, and attitudes of people were seen as static and a hinderance to social change. According to Myrdal, these were rationalizations for lack of policy for instituting change in the conditions of life. The lack of response to poverty was apologetic and explained away by pointing to the system of beliefs, social structure, low economic productivity, and climate. It was to some extent a justification for the superior status of Western society and culture backed by ideas of the survival of the fittest (Myrdal, 1970). Colonial policy, at least in one country, as one writer sums it up, was directed by “benevolent paternalism" (Nair, 1973: 123). In fact Myrdal states that the interests and concerns of Western leaders and interventionists in developing countries were not (ariented toward. either awakening the masses of people to their interests, instituting radical reforms, or toward making "genuine democracy" possible. All their sympathies were with the privileged classes in the underdeveloped countries and not with the impoverished masses. They were readily prepared to condone the absence of reforms in underdeveloped countries, or the perversion of reforms, preferring stability--in fact, a sort of continuation of colonial practices (Myrdal, 1970:435-36). With the movement toward de-colonization, however, many of the Western assumptions concerning change and progress became suspect and were rejected, not only by the indigenous people, but also by Westerners interested in these countries. According to Myrdal, colonial theory was given up and a "protest ideology" adopted. All the offensive elements in the old colonial theory were dropped. But a new kind of bias set in which did away with a rigorous analysisof social reality. Economic development and growth as the basis of development and change became the new concern, and the "spread effect" was adopted. But the model of economics did not take social conditions and social forces into account. The "non-economic factors" were either totally ignored or, if their existence was acknowledged, they did not enter into the economic equations that were charted. In either case, they failed "to explain what the neglect of these factors implied for the validity of their research" (Myrdal, 1970:11-12). This was partly the result of over-optimism concerning change and development via industrialization and education. Development was viewed as a linear process in which countries pass through stages of growth similar to the developed countries. Colonial theory which had earlier emphasized the influence of climate, secial structure, institutions, attitudes, and values as causes of poverty was ignored or abandoned (Myrdal, 1970; Frank, 1967; Grandstaff, 1974). This led to another form of status quo somewhat similar to the one practiced in the colonial period, but now under the guise of "change." This was the diffusion of liberalism in economics, education IO and social sciences. In the context of India, for example, the views of both British and Indian reformers were that: Progress . . . must emanate from forces within the society, generated by education and enlightenment. They were content to leave matters "in the hands of the school- master . . . ." This faith in education by the "school- master" was shared alike by British and Indian opinion (Nair, 1973:136-37). The general reactions to colonial government rules were essentially political, that is, desiring self-rule and the elimination of the British presence. In the Indian context, only Gandhi was con- cerned with both the immediate goals, and the long-term future. He had a realistic appraisal of Indian reality and problems and he sought to relate means and ends which were intrinsically indigenous both in conception and in the solutions he devised. However, inde- pendence and the rejection of colonialism led, ironically, to a greater adoption of western patterns of development. This was facilitated by the expansion of education, industrialization, and ideas concerning development from the West. With respect to the idea of change through education, . . both the leadership of these countries and the international agencies gave unquestioned priority to the setting up of "modern" systems rather than to theoretical research into the development-linked factors in education. However, at the same time, the classical conception of education, as concerned mainly with the promotion of cultural continuity, was revised. The dimension of change not only entered into the conception of the objectives of education but came to the forefront in both practical and theoretical preoccupation with education by educators and social scientists (Aran, Adler, and Eisenstadt, 1972:30). And, as with other areas that came under the rubric of the diffusion of innovation, "a rather one-sided and somewhat over-optimistic II expectation as to the ability of the modern, i.e., western-type, education to produce change," set in (Aran, Adler, and Eisenstadt, 1972:30). Some educationists and social scientists have refined their tools in order to explain more efficiently the causes of change. Educational economists, for instance, have attempted through inter- national comparisons to establish the economic value of education, and by the use of quantitative indicators to determine its contribu- tion to economic growth. This, as one writer states, is the "technique of 'keeping up with the Joneses'" (Blaugh, l969:7). The ”stages of educational growth" (Harbison and Myers, 1964; 1969) represents well the linear progression into which countries are arranged in a hierarchy of proximity and distance from the "Joneses" whoever they are and however they are defined. More recently, some have reformulated their stand, both on theoretical and practical levels concerning education as instrument of development and change. They now acknowledge that aggregate expansion and growth of education may perhaps contribute to disequi- librium in society, that it has somehow failed to lead to social and egalitarian reforms, and this has led to rethinking on the role of education in social change. The model which stated that "development could be achieved in very large part through economic growth," has "lost its attraction," for at least one writer (Curle, 1973:114). Another phase in the cycle of the relationship of education to change has set in. The focus is on the "human factor" in development, defined in a variety of ways. 12 According to some, change must now occur first at the level of individual "consciousness," by "raising of the individuals' general level of awareness" (Curle, 1973:134). In analyzing the factors which prevent man from creating and providing for his own and others well-being, attention has shifted to the individual. Curle posits a "counter-system" to the system of exploitation, competition, and materialism, which he considers wrong. The "counter-system" he states is psychologically based, and is to be achieved through the "efforts" of individuals. Individ'uals' characteristics and traits posited by other social scientists as necessary for change are: empathy (Lerner, 1958); "openness to innovation," "disposition to form and hold opinions," time orientation which is present and future, rather than past oriented, and a whole "complex of attitudes and values that we con- sider important in defining modern man" (Inkeles, 1966:138-50). Such criteria are considered desirable as opposed to others which presumably describe the personality of traditional man: fatalism, particularism, ascribed status, etc. In short, it is from the vantage point of the criteria of being "modern" that others are seen to be lacking (Frank, 1972; Rudolph and Rudolph, 1967). While some writers have done speculative work on the role of individuals in social change, others have set about to verify it by drawing on empirical data. Of the many social scientists who have focused their attention on the individual and have advocated a change in individual motives, desires, attitudes and values in order that social change can be guaranteed, few have spelled out their position 13 as explicitly as David C. McClelland (1969). Armed with the "need for Achievement" hypothesis, McClelland has done comparative studies of several countries in order to show the impact of achievement on economic growth, and where growth is slow the motive to achieve is shown to be low. He has, moreover, devised and implemented programs whereby the "impulse" to achieve could be infused in a population by education. From a somewhat relativistic perspective on education, by which social scientists and educationists were content to describe educational phenomena and the maintenance of cultures and traditions to which education, in a variety of forms, contributed; there has been a shift toward an overriding concern with changing institutions and customs through education, with establishing a functional relationship between education and other social, cultural and economic institutions. A third general concern has been with the beliefs, attitudes and values of individuals (Gezi, 1971), and how these hinder social change and development. A variety of methods has been devised to change individual attitudes, values, and motives in order to establish and guarantee modernization and development. In the literature on the "human factor" there are variations in emphasis put upon particular traits and characteristics considered important for social change. The particular individual attributes which function as essential ingredients for change may vary, as also the type of change envisaged may differ. But the overriding and encompassing concern is with determining the influence of the presence 14 or lack of particular individual attributes and characteristics and their relationship to change or lack of it. In this study I will explore two educational programs from India. One is a program of psychological education undertaken by David C. McClelland to motivate economic achievement in individuals. Another is the Scheme of Basic Education devised by Mahatma Gandhi to transform individuals and reconstruct Indian society. First the general characteristics and objectives of the two educational programs, their implementation, and outcomes and results will be discussed; secondly, a critical analysis and evaluation of the premises and assumptions of the two programs and some of the limitations in undertaking and explaining social change by advocating changes in individual effort, awareness, consciousness, achievement, and individual transformation of values will be presented. One program is essentially western in conception and execu- tion, and the goals sought are also dictated by certain western biases concerning social change and development. There is the recognition or acceptance of the view that funderdeveloped" countries require directed and rapid change, at the same time is the acknowledge- ment of the difficulties its entails. Furthermore, there is implicit a belief that: . . . the increase in the production of material goods is necessary not only as a means of attaining a more satisfactory state of society, but even as a condition of economic health (Dumont, 1964:10). An educational program which exemplifies this orientation was under- ‘taken by David C. McClelland in India. 15 The Scheme of Basic Education conceived by Mahatma Gandhi for inducing social change in India was intrinsically Indian in origin, both in the ends which Basic Education was devised to achieve and the means utilized for their accomplishment. Gandhi, according to Singer, "brought elements of Indian religious traditions into service of political, social, and economic reforms." He harnessed "his 'spirituality' to a philosophy and program of social reform . . ." (Singer, 1972:34). Gandhi was not opposed to change. In fact, as several writers point out, he broke away from "orthodox interpreta- tions of Hinduism" by identifying the essential normative system with a social and altruistic ethic (Gupta, 1971; Rudolph and Rudolph, 1967; and Singer, 1972). Nor was Gandhi against change in the material conditions of life. He was not only concerned with problems of poverty, of unemployment, of the urban-rural diachotomies, but was the only Indian leader who attempted to make them central issues in programs of development and change. He sought to devise ways and means which would help solve these problems, and Basic Education was A one of them. Gandhi was, however, against development which meant material growth, induStrial production, in short development for the sake of development. His one concern was, to use a subtitle to a recent book, Small is Beautiful, to devise "Economics As If People Mattered" (Schumacher, 1973). As this study will document, the types of social change envisaged differ radically in the positions of McClelland and Gandhi, and there are variations also in the methods of implementing it. For example, McClelland is concerned with educational training of 16 innovators and entrepreneurs, and Gandhi's concern is with reaching the masses and providing education to improve the conditions of all people. However, the ways in which social change is to be obtained are similar-~through changing individuals, individual effort, aware- ness, consciousness, achievement, and individual transformation of values. Each advocates a particular type of education to unfold particular qualities in individuals. Each in his own way attempts to explain social change by recourse to the individual. In the shift of attention to the individual as an agent of social change, factors which are external and which impinge upon and constrain action are either recognized as a hinderance to individual self-realization and viewed in moral terms as being evil and there- fore bad; or the social conditions are narrowed down to the level of the individuals' situational environment which the researcher or the agent of social change is able to manipulate and control. ,In both cases, individual self-realization and social well-being are to be obtained through proper education and training. The major purpose in presenting the two cases is to discuss them within the framework of the individualistic psychological approaches in social science. At a level of abstraction and general- ization both provide explanations of social change which can be sub- sumed under individualistic psychological approaches. Methodological Limitations Programs of development and social change which focus on individual needs, desires, attitudes, values, and motives as crucial 17 determinants of change constitute the basic data for this research. The content of the programs and the forms they take may, however, vary. For example, some are pilot projects undertaken in a particu- lar village or community (Fraser, 1968); others are experimental programs to induce in specific groups of individuals the need for achievement (McClelland, 1969); still others are descriptions and explanations of national schemes of social change, such as the com- munity development or Basic Education efforts undertaken in India. Available also are some evaluative studies of such programs but these too are premised on psychological presuppositions concerning individual beliefs, attitudes, and values in social change. This research will focus on a fairly restricted body of data, selected for its usefulness in demonstrating the uses of the psycho- logical approach to social change. In the case of India several possibilities present themselves, for example, Basic Education, Community Development, diffusion of innovation, training in need Achievement, and other specific projects of individual attitude and value changes undertaken by social scientists and educationists. From a survey of these bodies of literature the Scheme of Basic Education and the need Achievement training programs were selected. These two programs appear potentially most fruitful for exploring the uses of the "psychological" and "individualistic" approaches in undertaking and explaining social change. The selection of these two programs out of numerous other studies available from India was made because: (1) these two educa- tional programs have been documented extensively, (2) more literature 18 is available on them than on others at the present time, (3) both encompass training and education as important elements in social change, (4) both types of education programs have been implemented: one on an experimental basis, and the other on a mass scale, and (5) both can be described as part of recorded history, although both are extant in one form or another, and continue to be studied and researched. In order to analyze and evaluate the two educational programs certain parameters will be outlined. These arise partly from the study and examination of the two educational programs themselves, and from a study of the theoretical literature on the subject of indi- vidualistic psychological approaches. An attempt is made to provide a framework for the discussion and analysis of the cases. The dis- cussion of each educational program will be circumscribed by the framework provided here. McClelland's educational program for changing motivations is based on theories in psychology. learning theory, behavioristic psychology and economic theory (McClelland, 1969). He focuses on specific motives which are considered important in explaining social change. By the use of social science methods--standard test instru- ments, pre- and post tests, controlled comparison, rigorous evalua- tion and presentation of data--he attempts to establish relationships between particular properties of individuals--need to achieve and certain external criteria--increase and expansion of business enter- prise, for example. He selects a small and limited group of indi- viduals identified by a set of dominant characteristics and attributes 19 which then function as important variables within the framework of explanation. The training program in psychological education itself serves as an intervening variable whose effects on individual motivation and in turn on business enterprise the authors wish to test. Consequently, McClelland's program is very much in the main- stream of social science research. It is based upon a set of theories; he attempts to establish relationships between specified properties, and he utilizes social science methods to evaluate his findings. The Gandhian Scheme of Basic Education did not have its origins in a particular social science thedry or model of change and development. But it was embedded in an ideology or philosophy, or a combination thereof. Gandhi's concern was not to test a hypothesis or prove a theory, or to focus on any specific, identifiable group of individuals, but to advocate through the program a total trans- formation of individual consciousness. His concern was with the viability of one set of ideas over another. By formulating ideas into programs of constructive action--for example, through Basic Education--he attempted to convince and persuade pe0ple of the necessity for change. Social change would result from the transforma- tion of individual attitudes, values and desires and by their commit- ment to an alternative set of values. Since Gandhi's program of change is broad-based it is some- what difficult to evaluate the application of his ideas in action: (1) the application of his ideas was not rigorous, consequently the 20 form the ideas took in Basic Education was merely an imagery or a shadow of the ideas as expressed by him, and (2) there was no built in system of evaluation, as a result evaluations of Basic Education that are available are in the nature of aposteriori studies. Most of these are descriptive, a few examine the internal workings of the schools. Consequently, it is somewhat of a more difficult enterprise to conduct an inquiry into the aims and objectives of Basic Education and to evaluate their success vis-a-vis their con- sistency and conformity with Gandhian ideals without at the same time doing an injustice to those ideals. A further complication that arises with respect to the analysis of Gandhian ideas in practice is that in the process of formulation of his ideas in action, the ideas were eventually identified with the person. The powerful force his ideas exercised on the Indian intelligensia, on the common man, and the whole course of Indian history, are now part of recorded fact; but the idolatry of the ideas of Gandhi became inseparable from the person. Although the institutionalization of these ideas did take place, it was more a form of ritual observance. Within the workings of Basic Education itself, those of his ideas which related to personal and civic virtues were of dominant concern. Whether Basic Education transforms individual attitudes, values and desires in a particular direction rather than another is open to question. There are no comparative studies of children from different types of schools, for instance, to verify the claims of transformation of values through Basic Education. 21 Organization of the Dissertation In Chapter I, a statement of the problem, the purpose and significance of the study, some methodological limitations and the organization of the dissertation are presented. In Chapter II, a survey of theoretical literature on individualistic psychological approaches in the context of social change theory is presented. Also, literature that provides a framework for analyzing such approaches to social change is reviewed. In Chapter III, McClelland's training program to modify individual achievement motivation and guarantee social change is described. This includes a presentation of the stated goals and purpose; the implementation of the program, and the assessment and outcomes of the program in achievement training. In Chapter IV, a critical analysis of the premises and assumptions of McClelland's education program is provided. Some of the limitations of explaining social change by advocating changes in particular individual psychological states, and the implications and consequences of such an undertaking for policy are discussed. In Chapter V, the Gandhian Scheme of Basic Education to transform individuals and reconstruct society is described. The implementation of Gandhi's ideas on education, and the outcomes and results of the Basic Education program are discussed. In Chapter VI, an analysis of the Gandhian philosophy of social change is presented; the strengths and weaknesses of the 22 philosophy are discussed; and the limitations of programs of change based upon his particular approach are examined. Chapter VII includes a summary and conclusion of the dis- sertation. In this chapter also, a discussion of the relationship between individualistic psychological approaches and education is presented. CHAPTER II INDIVIDUALISTIC PSYCHOLOGICAL APPROACHES IN THE CONTEXT OF SOCIAL CHANGE THEORY Introduction In this chapter a survey of the literature on individualistic psychological approaches in explanation of social change isprovided. In both the presentation of this literature and in the discussion of alternative approaches, I shall rely heavily on certain epistemo- logical and methodological issues within social science itself. The issue of explanation within social science is a very complex and historically a long standing one. It is not my purpose to cover all aspects of the epistemological and methodological points of the debate, but to outline only those aspects of social science approaches which are directly relevant to the present study. This will be done by first placing the psychological approaches in historical perspec- tive by describing other approaches within social science to which the psychological approaches were a response. Secondly, an outline of the conceptual framework and methodology as they obtain in the various approaches concerned with explaining social change and development will be provided. For purposes of clarity, the various approaches are arranged in different sections, not necessarily in chronological order, as these ideas have been held simultaneously. In fact, they were used 23 24 over the same time period in the past and both co-exist today. Moreover, no attempt is made here to legislate the adequacy of one approach over another. Within social science, as one writer points out, all that obtains are empirical generalizations which state relationships of properties based on observations. Social science has few theoretical hypotheses, and empirical generalizations do produce useful explanations whether or not these explanations are considered to be ultimate (Brown, 1964). Positivistic Approaches Within Social Science In this section some limitations of the positivistic approaches in social science are examined from the point of view of the human factor exclusively. The purpose here is to provide the historical setting which gave rise to the development of the individ- ualistic psychological approaches as a reSponse to extreme forms of positivism in social science. Positivism in social science, as expressed especially in the writings of Durkheim, exercised a powerful influence and con- tinues to do so on present practitioners. Durkheim's contribution lay in attaching importance to the primacy of social facts in the study of social behavior. "Social facts" as crystallization of human activity are observable because they are collective, widespread, and diffused within a group. While emerging from human activity, they exercise a coercive force upon individuals. Social facts consist "of ways of acting, thinking, and feeling, external to the individual, and endowed with a power of coercion, by reason of which they control him" (Durkheim, 1966z3). 25 In general, the collective and the normative become the focus of analysis. The study of norms, especially those exemplified in roles and clusters of roles that are embodied in institutions serve as the unit of analysis. The arena of investigation, then, is institutionalized behavior (see also Murphy, 1971:86). The concern is with system maintenance--the interrelations of roles, the interrelations of institutions, i.e., how institutions fit together. The survival of society is taken as a given, the ultimate end of behavior and the function of institutions is to contribute to its maintenance. The conceptualization of "ends" or "purposes," then, stops with a notion of the survival of society which operates theoretically in much the same way as do homeostasis and species survival in the biological sciences. Analysis tends to be synchronic and static, and concerned with equilibrium, with a smoothly functioning social system in which individuals perform roles as actors on stage (Beattie, 1964; Homans, 1964; Murphy, 1971; Alavi, n.d.; Wilhelm, 1967). Durkheim's dictum that social facts should be treated as things became an axiom (Murphy, 1971). Within social science, general propositions are about the interactions of institutions, about social structures, and characteristics of societies, and not about the behavior of "individual consciousness" (Homans, 1964:810). The assumptions of structural-functionalists, according to another writer are: . . . given the division of labour is society, social roles which individuals occupy are reciprocally and collec- tively "functional" so that society as a whole constitutes a harmoniously integrated system (Alavi, n.d.). 26 The concept of roles is central. Individuals play out their pre- scribed roles in accordance to rules laid out by the social structure (Alavi, n.d.). There is the tendency in this approach to reify institutions and social structure and ignore the individual as an active, willing agent, who thinks, chooses, and acts. This model, according to Alavi, does not . . . allow for activities which undermine the structure itself, nor that men may contend with other men about the nature of their society and aspire to alter the structure itself (Alavi, n.d.). Since the concern is with showing how the institutions fit together to maintain society as an "organic whole," this approach is unable to tackle change within and of institutions. Its focus is on "processes which are involved in equilibrium and stability" (Nisbet, 1969:283). In order to confront the issue of change, contemporary functionalists, according to Nisbet, seek "to account for the sources of change through exploration of the properties of abstract social systems . . ." (Nisbet, 1969:275). With the trend toward comparison of societies and cultures, sources of change are posited as exogenous. Concern, consequently, is with the institutional processes for the orderly transfer and transition of norms, ideas, and values, since these are perceived as the determinants of action. In order for change to occur it is considered necessary that a diffusion of norms, values and institu- tions take place. Within social science, the analysis and juxta- position of divergent types of social institutions, norms, and values is achieved or legitimized by the use of ideal-types which, 27 presumably, are neutral, value-free, and objective descriptions of empirical phenomena. For example, in the study of modernization assumptions are made which represent examples of an ideal-typical approach. Modernization is viewed as an inexorable force. For modernization to occur, a breakdown of the traditional social and cultural forms is necessary, and if this does not happen "then the forces of tra- ditionalism must have been too strong and we should expect a failure of modernization and a persistence of the traditional forms" (Singer, 1968:431). In the Indian context, as Singer elaborates: These assumptions have led to sweeping generalizations about the incompatibility between the joint family, the caste system, and Hinduism, on the one hand, and the forces of modern industry, urbanization, science, technology, and education, on the other (1968:431-32). The consequences of these assumptions in research is either to demonstrate "the breakdown of these 'traditional' institutions under the influence of the forces of modernization," or else to show how "the persistence of the 'traditional' institutions is a major obstacle to modernization" (1968:432). And when it is found that both tend to coexist, then the tendency is to consider the society to be in a state of transition. This tends not only to abstract institutions and groups but also fails to provide an explanation of the processes of adaptive change (Singer, 1968:432). The ideal-type as a construct conceived by Weber was not a hypothesis or an average, nor was it a model of "what ought to be." Just as with institutions, norms and values, the ideal-type was viewed as a "thing" often confused with actual reality. The 28 ideal-type is regarded "as a procrustean bed into which to force the data and ideal-types have been hypostisized, so that they assume the character of real forces" (Zeitlin, 1969:120). Institutional or group concepts are characteristically "open— ended" and as such take on ambiguity in meaning. The tendency in the use of such concepts is to attribute "non-observable properties . . . to equally non-observable group identities" (Brodbeck, 1958:6). The use of group or macroscopic concepts embodying "properties over and above the individuals making up the group" is described as meta- physical holism. It is a view which "maintains that there are so- called wholes, group identities which have undefinable properties of their own" (Brodbeck, l958:3). Whole group, institutional, or holistic concepts, such as those defining attitudes of authoritarianism-non-authoritarianism tend to be open concepts, and, as such, imprecise and vague in definition. “The more macroscopic the concept, the wider its penumbra of vagueness is apt to be" (Brodbeck, l958:5). The use of ideal-type concepts in comparative investigations presents several difficulties. They screen out perceptions of the particular and the exceptional that contradict dominant trends and motifs. Such theoretical screening is especially inimical to the analysis of social change because it eliminates from con- sideration latent, deviant, and minority alternatives (Rudolph and Rudolph, 1967:7). Conflict and deviance within an equilibrium model are dysfunctional, since the concern, as before, is with providing individuals with appropriate roles in order that the changed institutions can function for the maintenance of society. 29 In an attempt to reduce "phenomena to facts," in the prac- tice of positivism the tendency has been ". . . to assume a homology, if not a unity, between the phenomenology of the mind and that of the world external to it" (Murphy, 1971:84). Individualistic P§ychological Approaches in Explanation of SociaT'Change Reactions to the positivistic trends in social science have preoccupied philosophers and social scientists concerned with questions of epistemology and methodology in the study of man and society. The general rubric of "individualistic" and "psychological" approaches encompasses a variety of different models, subcategories, and variations in emphasis and interpretations depending upon the research interests of the writers and the particular problem of social change that is explored. But the focus of analysis is the individual and his characteristics, attributes and particular psychological states. Some of the types of individualistic psychological approaches which obtain in social science are quite wide-ranging and cover a variety of complex frameworks and positions. The focus of some studies is on national character (for a critique see Harris, 1968; Pocock, 1961); others examine child-raising practices and their effect on personality (for a critique see Harris, 1968; Aberle, 1961). Some are concerned with particular individual attitudes, values, motives, and desires and the relationship of these to external change or lack of it (for a critique see Durkheim, 1964; Singer, 1966; Goheen et al., 1958; and White, 1949). Even more 30 sophisticated models of the psychological approaches are embodied in such ideas as the "image of limited goods" (Foster, 1968), and the "culture of poverty" (Lewis, 1970). (For a critique of this model see Valentine, 1968; and for the psychodynamic model of social change see Kunkel, 1970.) A general response to positivism in social science is that what "really exist are 'individuals and their actions and reactions'" (Novak, 1968:149). Action is determined not by rules or social laws, but by the exercise of individual will and choice. The historical and philOSOphical antecedents to this view are found in a particular view of man and society which is viewed as self-sufficient, independent, autonomous, and as a "non-social moral being" (Dumont, 1965:15). This is essentially a western con- ception, according to Dumont, who traces the genesis of "man as an individual" through religious and secular texts in the history of western thought. He distinguishes this view of man from man as "the empirical subject of speech, thought and will, indivisible sample of mankind," which he calls the “particular man" found in all societies and cultures (1965:15). At issue here is the analytical distinction between the holistic view that men are parts of a social whole and "socially determined" beings, which Dumont claims belongs to the traditional conception of society as "universitas". This gave way to the notion of "societas" in which individual men come together to form association. 31 The notion of the individual as a "whplg_being, a private individual" (Dumont, 1965:19), however, led to a widespread tendency in social science "which takes society to consist of individuals prior to groups or relationships that they constitute or 'make' by combination, more or less of their own accord" (1965:30). Society is "deduced, from inherent properties or qualities of man taken as an autonomous being independently or any social or political attachment" (1965:29). Isolated, independent individuals come together to form a social whole via a contract (1965:32). In explanation and analysis of reality the "social facts" of Durkheim are reduced to "individual facts" (Alavi, n.d.) which in turn are narrowed down to psychological states or patterns of behavior (Geertz, 1973). Social scientists who are interested in understanding and explaining individual psychology and the contributions that individ- uals make to social change tend to emphasize the following elements: 1. Social science methods must focus on understanding the subjective factor in social change. 2. Individual behavior is the result of motives, values, attitudes, and propensities. 3. Individual attitudes, verbal and non-verbal, are the locus of social science enterprise. Inquiry consequently is narrowed down to a specific activity and analysis similarly bound by a concern with specific individual propensities, dispositions, values, desires, and interests which motivate action. The concern in analysis is not with exploring sources of change and explanation of change of "abstract social systems," but "with the nature of social change considered as an 32 empirical process in social behavior through historical time" (Nisbet, 1969:279). Within the arena of social science, the explanation of social action, according to Homans, "is given not by any distinc- tively sociological proposition but by the propositions of learning theory in psychology" (Homans, 1964:814). Psychological proposi- tions concerning the behavior of individuals are all that obtain in social science, according to Homans, and psychological proposi- tions are sufficient for explanation of social phenomena. Psycho- logical propositions are general, they constitute deductive systems that explain human behavior (Homans, 1964). "The laws of human behavior do not change." If they cannot explain everything social it is due to a lack of "factual informa- Ition . . . and not to the propositions themselves." All attempts to explain social phenomenon which are deductive, are essentially psychological explanations. "The general propositions of sociology are in fact psychological" (Homans, 1964:817). In order to correct the structural-functional view that began with the Durkheimian axiom that behavior conforms to norms and roles, and which consequently denied or ignored individual initiative in action, those who adopt a psychological approach focus on the individual as the source of norms and values. The positivistic view of the social system and the normative structure in which the individual plays his role and to which he conforms is construed to be embedded in, and can be reduced to, psychological elements. The psychological attributes which constitute human nature are also 33 viewed as pr0positions which "account for" it (Nisbet, 1969: 296). The psychological framework, furthermore, assumes that the behaviors of all individuals in a group "can be explained within the context of a theory of psychology . . ." (Brodbeck, 1958:16). Or alternatively, the explanation of the behavior of an individual can be generalized to the behaviors of all individuals in a group. Analysis of Individualistic Psychological—Appppaches The emphasis on individual attributes, to the exclusion of institutional settings in explanation of social change produces a one-sided picture. Explanation of social phenomena by reference to psychological states tends "to root values and norms in the supposed needs of the individuals pgp_§gf (Mills, 1959:160). But the needs themselves require an understanding of the social reality in which they find fulfillment. This does not imply a denial of reality to individuals, but only that the life of an individual cannot be understood minUs his institutions, within which his life is enacted. The life of an individual is made up of an "external biography" of roles which can be understood only in a context of institutions. Along with the "external biography" one must consider the "internal and 'psychological' features of man"--his conscience, emotions, feelings, self-image, and his mind. But beyond the parameters of physiological imperatives or limits, individual likes and dislikes, perceptions of self and others are also socially patterned. 34 The motivations of men, . . . are to be understood in terms of the vocabularies of motive that prevail in a society and of social changes and confusions among such vocabularies (Mills, 1969:162). Social scientists who adopt the position that it is possible to explain human behavior by definition of a specific set of subjective states as expressed in attitudes, opinions, and values, tend to assume a degree of rational self-consciousness and self-knowledge on the part of individuals. But there are few individuals who can be expected to know and understand the causes of their conduct and feelings, and most individuals tend to reconsider "conduct in the light of different motives" (Grunbaum, 1953:774). Although behavior is determined by peoples' motives, expectations and values, a social scientist cannot ignore the dif- ference between what people "actually do“ and what they "believe they 'ought to do'" (Beattie, 1964:37-38), otherwise, the social scientist is likely to confuse motives and values with overt acts of behavior or to assume a perfect fit between attitudes, values and beliefs on the one hand and action on the other (Wicker, 1969). Although individuals do have beliefs and values and may act on them, a social scientist cannot "with impunity, wholly ignore the differ- ence between what people think of the world and what the world is like" (Brodbeck, 1954:143).1 1Recently, "Structuralism" as expounded by several well- known social scientists is an attempt to understand and explain the "deep structures" of the mind and "the possibility of innate knowl- edge not derived from experience" (Stent, 1975:1053). But since this is an area which at the moment, to my knowledge, is not con- cerned with the relationship between social change and "deep structures" I will not explore it further. 35 This is not a denial of the importance of motives in human action. In fact, the nature and functioning of the individual characteristics, and individual mind can be grasped and understood only by the use of psychological terms and concepts (Brodbeck, 1954, 1958; Beattie, 1964; Harris, 1968). Psychology has an important contribution to make to “an understanding of individual health and disease" (Harris, 1968:458). And psychological interests both in the physiological factors in human behavior and also the conditioning factors that lead an indi- vidual to act in a specific way do provide important explanatory grounds for individual behavior. It is perfectly legitimate to try to find out what is going on "inside peoples' heads," to find out how people think, and feel. But, as Harris contends, in explanation of socio-cultural change, it is "less risky" to undertake other types of cultural and social investigations. . . psychological studies are especially vulnerable to criticisms which challenge their evidential foundations. This difficulty increases in direct proportion to the size and socio-cultural complexity of the population from which the typical impressionistic vignettes are derived (Harris, 1968:414). It is a form of idealism, according to Harris, to advocate that a particular type of personality is both necessary and sufficient con- dition for certain types of institutions to surface. Although institutional transformations required "appropriate personality types" they are themselves not sufficient. Besides, the creation of "appropriate personality types" itself requires institutional changes. Moreover, Harris cautions, "Human personalities, like ideas, are potentially infinite in variety." The issues within 36 social science have to do with "why specific cultures manifest regular differences and similarities. Explanations by reduction to individual personality would be impossible" (Harris, 1968:457). Other writers point to the limitations of the terms and con- cepts and to the assumptions within psychology, not just in terms of their application to individuals in unfamiliar cultures. Terms and concepts "derived from psychological researches in Western society may lead--and indeed have 1ed--to gross distortions" (Beattie, 1964:28). Concepts which define attitudes and clinical states require that a choice be made "from an almost infinite variety of symptoms those which can be used reliably to define the term in question.” Consequently, the explicit definition of concepts, in order that they can enter into laws is a problem which psychologists must address. Problems remain, however, even if the problem of definition could be overcome, in that "the fittingness of a behavioristic definition varies from culture to culture" (Brodbeck, l958:5). To put it differently, In all societies, concrete manifestations of behavior, verbal or nonverbal, result from complicated interactions of specific personalities whose repertoires of rules,- especially when it comes to the rules for interpreting or breaking rules, often seem to have little in common (Harris, 1968:591). There are limitations both with respect to definition on psychological terms and concepts, and their explanatory scope. The dilemma is that both psychologists and social scientists are concerned with the same subject matter--"people in society"-- but the questions each asks differ (Beattie, 1964:26). Psychology 37 focuses on the individual, and other social scientists, such as anthropologists and sociologists, on the "society and culture the individual is jpf (Beattie, 1964:26). Each is a legitimate and autonomous enterprise, they do not mutually exclude each other. Society does not exist apart from its members. Each, however, calls for a different "level of analysis" and "different methods." Psychological explanations cannot suffi- ciently explain social phenomena. All explanation is a way of accounting for reality, and as such it abstracts, but the abstraction occurs at different levels and requires different sets of premises (Beattie, 1964). The difficulty is that social scientists do use terms and concepts drawn from psychology. Even writers who are not at all psychologically oriented tend to use psychological terms and con- cepts. The use of psychological terms and concepts to describe whole cultures was a common practice among the culture and personality and the historical-particularistic schools of anthropology (e.g., Harris, 1968:395). But while the "psychological idiom“ is appro- priate for describing individual characteristics it is not adequate in explaining socio-cultural change (Harris, 1968:404). The issue, according to Brodbeck, who approaches it on an analytical level, is between the relationship of group concepts and those referring to individuals. She distinguishes between "the nature of tgpm§_or concepts of social science," and "the nature of its law§_and theories and their relationship in turn to those in other areas." Terms and concepts refer to meaning and hence matters 38 of definition; laws and theories require reduction and therefore explanation (Brodbeck, 1958:1)., According to Brodbeck, psychological terms and concepts in description of social phenomena can be legitimately used. This statement is based on the premise that all group characteristics, attributes, and properties are definable in terms of individual behaviors. To do otherwise--that is, to hold to the view that group characteristics are undefinable, that they are not reducible to "descriptive relations"--is to attribute to the group the property of a "superentity" having its own aims and purpose. I The use of a psychological theory of individual behavior, on the other hand, in explanation of social phenomena is a form of "reductive explanation," that is, it attempts to explain the phenomena in a given field in terms of another field that is microscopic to it. The problem in the use of such an approach is the inability "to generalize from the pattern of interaction between two individuals to the pattern of interaction among many individuals" (Holt and Turner, 1966:27-28). While it is appropriate for psychologists to analyze individual behavior by examining motives and desires that activate individuals, questions that can be asked concerning inten- tions and motivations of individuals "have little relevance to institutional analysis" (Beattie, 1964:55). Beattie further dis- tinguishes between the two types of analysis: 39 . . . questions which may usefully be asked about social institutions are often quite inappropriate in regard to individual people. It is entirely sensible to ask what are the social functions of an institution like marriage: it is very much less so to ask what are the social functions of particular husbands or wives (1964:55; see also Brodbeck, 1968). It is very easy to confuse the two frames of reference, but as Nisbet points out, somewhat bluntly, social scientists “dare not confuse a proposition by which we account for an aspect of reality with the nature of reality" (Nisbet, 1969:294). At the level of empirical generalizations,2 however, in sociological explanations, psychological involvement may be seen as intervening variables in the functional relationship between two sociological elements. Similarly, from the standpoint of individual psychology. the sociocultural element may be seen as the intervening variable in the functional whole of the human personality (Goldschmidt, 1966:134). Brodbeck describes the characteristic features of all social sciences which point to a lack of closure, completeness, and per- fection in comparison with the physical sciences. The separation of variables into stimulus and response variables, for example, is artificial and points to imperfection. The same holds for all social sciences. The use of statistics to overcome some of the shortcomings simply points to "how much can be ignored, particularly of the individual variance, and prediction still be possible" (Brodbeck, 1958:22). 2These are defined as statements of regular relationship of properties based on observations. Empirical generalizations appeal to further empirical generalizations. They lead to successive puzzles with no clear end in sight. Social science has a few theoretical hypotheses, and empirical generalizations produce useful explanations whether or not they are ultimate. (Robert Brown, ,Explanations in Social Science, 1963.) 40 The general implications are: (1) that no individual social science can attempt to explain everything; (2) that each social science is dependent upon the findings of other social sciences; and (3) that there is dependence upon terms and concepts from one social science to another. While the subject matter is the same, the approach taken, the questions asked, and the level of analysis differ. "Explanation in any field is not absolute, but relative to a set of premises" (Brodbeck, 1954:155). It is "a matter of empirical determination," according to Brodbeck, whether group behavior can be reduced to laws about individual behavior. It is a "matter of fact. And matters of fact cannot be legislated into existence," they have to be empirically determined (Brodbeck, 1958:20). The "group sciences" according to Brodbeck, are here to stay, although the likelihood of "a set of macroscopic laws permitting the prediction of the 'state' of society (i.e., the values of the group variables) at all time from its state at any given time," is remote (1958:21). Yet, on the other hand, there are limitations in the use of reductive explanations that can be applied to "complex macro- social phenomena" (Holt and Turner, 1966:27). For the purposes of analysis, in the studies which focus on psychological factors as elements in social change, two dominant trends can be identified. One holds that there are certain stable motives in individuals. Social change is viewed to be the result of individual pursuit of self-interest and desires and maximization of values, therefore social change can be furthered: (a) by individual 41 expression and realization of preferences and interests, (b) by steering these through the use of the right kind of education, and (c) by providing individuals with incentives and rewards. Individual self-realization occurs through pursuit of self- interest "in the form of acquisition, accumulation, and maximization" (Weisskoph, 1951:199). Social change follows once this is guaranteed to all individuals, and a "harmony of interests" will come to prevail. This, as Weisskoph points out, is essentially a lpsychocultural device "to justify economic egoism by asserting that it is at least socially beneficial" (1951:199). Another dominant trend evident in the literature which falls in the domain of individual psychological approaches is the view that social change is caused by changes in peoples' attitudes, motives, values, and desires, and can be furthered: (a) by replacing one set or type of motives, values and desires by another; (b) by advocating a commitment to personal and social virtues through con- sciousness raising and proper education; and (c) creating a sense of community spirit and c00peration. The goal sought is the good of the whole. The social welfare of all is of predominant concern. Individual satisfaction and self- realization can be achieved only through "altruistic unselfishness" (Joshi, 1971:78). In the Gandhian cosmology, society is essentially "non-acquisitive," and “non-technocratic" (1971:79). In both cases, the focus of analysis is individual and particular psychological states. And, in both cases, education is the means for bringing about individual and social change. 42 In this chapter a summary of individual psychological approaches in the context of social change theories is provided. This serves as a basis of an inquiry and analysis of the two cases from India. That inquiry will begin with an inspection of, first, a Western model of development undertaken as an experimental educa- tion program known as "N_[need] Achievement training," whose advocate is David C. McClelland; and second, an indigenous model of develop- ment exemplified in the ideas and experiments of Mahatma Gandhi and expressed in and through the program of Basic Education. CHAPTER III McCLELLAND'S TRAINING PROGRAM TO MODIFY INDIVIDUAL ACHIEVEMENT MOTIVATION AND GUARANTEE SOCIAL CHANGE General Characteristics of McClelland's Theoretical Framework David C. McClelland is one of a number of social scientists to apply a theory in behavioral science to problems of development. He essentially views problems of social change to be those requiring changes in motivation and personality, that is, the creation of _r_1_ Achievement in each individual. At the societal level, change is viewed as the result of an ethic or ideology (McClelland, 1961, 1963, and 1969). McClelland is interested in "the motivational concerns which favor economic and social modernization" and his views are that certain "psychological preconditions for a 'modern' technical and social order" are imperative (1963:17). McClelland suggests that: . ideas are in fact more important in shaping history than purely materialistic arrangements . . . it is values, motives, or psychological forces that determine ultimately the rate of economic and social development (1963:18). The issue is one of changing Phuman valuesi (1963:28). It is inade- quate, according to McClelland, to hold to the view that changes in the economic, technical, and environmental factors will lead to 43 44 changes in human responses, which then will support the altered arrangements. Furthermore, he opposed the view that as people are exposed to modernizing factors in their environment--that is, urbanization, mass media, political participation, education, the use of money--they will inevitably be led to change their attitudes, beliefs, and values (Inkeles, 1966; Lerner, 1958; Rogers, 1969). These factors, according to McClelland, have failed to lead to desired responses in individuals. Over and over again technical assistance has failed to evoke automatically attitudes it should if it is to be considered a really effective source of attitude change (1969:30). ‘The provision of government aid, guarantees, and incentives in the form of opportunities to succeed and thus further economic development have not worked (1969:19). Re-arranging institutional and social conditions in order to change men's behaviors, by providing rewards and incentives for appropriate change in the desired direction, are not sufficient. Such programs are based on the "rational model" of economics which states that men will maximize their personal utility. This model, according to McClelland, is unable to specify the conditions under which change does or does not occur. McClelland sets out to discover those specific conditions or elements which account for variation in response to similar condi- tions. It is by using the psychological concept of achievement motivation, or p_Achievement, to account for the differences in response to similar conditions that an adequate explanation can be 45 considered. It is one specific motive that interests McClelland from the hierarchy of motives found in individuals (1969:43). And it is the association between this particular psychological character- ,istic (which he labels p_[need for] Achievement) and the entre- preneurial spirit which leads to social change. N Achievement is a characteristic found to varying degrees in all individuals. Need to achieve is a "relatively stable person- ality characteristic" (l969z2). But it is possible to manipulate disposition, motivation, personality--the structure of responses in individuals--to bring about desired economic change; "development of motivation" can lead to other types of development (1969:xii). While all individuals have a need to achieve, some are more endowed than others and this has important implications for development. The theory of motivation predicts that it is precisely those with high p_Achievement who are sensitive to changes in economic opportunities; whereas those with low p_Achieve- ment are not (l969z6). And, since motives are learned or acquired, they can be changed (1969:43). McClelland's theoretical framework includes two elements: one economic and the other psychological. Central to the economic model is the axiom: "Men act so as to maximize their interest(s) or return(s) over some time period, given the perceived constraints of the situation" (1969:21). But not all individuals are motivated to achieve economic gains and growth, as economists assume; they may also be motivated to achieve other things. McClelland explains the concepts of the rational economic model in order to describe the variations in the ways the model finds expression. 46 All individuals are maximizers, but not of the same things; some pursue life, others leisure, the Good. A man's behavior is rational in that he maximizes some thing (interests). Men have a variety of interests. To say "men get what they want," says little about "which things they come to want" (1969z9). - In maximization of the expected value of the outcome of an act, an individual pursues a particular strategy, and he has a certain perception of success or failure in investing or not investing. - The time period required also involves a perception of immediate or short term gain. - The way in which an individual perceives the constraints of the situation, and evaluates the situation and processes it, affect the maximization of interest over time (1969: 22). Because of the ambiguities embedded in the concepts of the rational economic model, in different contexts, the model takes different forms and is unable to explain economic development. "Certain patterns of terms lead to economic development, and certain patterns do not" (1969:23). Variations in the ways the model finds expression is the result of p_Achievement, according to McClelland. A second element of McClelland's theoretical framework is that it is only people with strong achievement motivation who display the attributes necessary for economic development: "concern for improvement, maximization of gains, minimization of time and effort, weighing difficulties realistically" (1969:338). It is this motive which leads to "vigorous economic activity." . . various aspects of p.Achievement behavior syndrome are precisely those that are necessary to make the rational model work in a way that promotes economic development (1969:23). A combination of psychological terms and concepts and economic terms and concepts constitute his framework. 47 The provision of incentives and opportunities or the alloca- tion of resources, which the economic framework permits, is not enough. In other words, the re-structuring of the situation is insufficient to bring about development. The structure of response to the situation of specific populations--their interests, strategies, time perspectives, and perceptions (1969:25). "In psychological language, it becomes important to increase p_Achieve- ment"(l969:26). Involved is an assumption that both these criteria--economic and psychological are imperative for economic development, but “not all people possess the characteristics of achievement motiva- tion in a sufficient degree to respond to economic incentives" (1969:339). The Experimental Context In order to test his theoretical framework, McClelland and his colleagues undertook a program to teach need achievement to a group of Indian businessmen, on the assumption that they would "take better advantage of existing economic opportunities,“ once they were trained (1969:338). To formulate the experiment, the authors drew upon a variety of experimental and clinical literature. From learning theory they took such variables as frequency of rewards, the meaningfulness of material learned, and recitation, as factors important to behavior change. From psychotherapy came the idea that warmth and empathy on the part of the therapist promotes more rapid improvement, 48 And, from the literature on attitude change were drawn the notions that "using reason or prestige to support an argument and affiliat- ing with a new reference group are variables that are crucial for developing new attitudes . . ." (1969:44). Motives are "clusters of expectancies" that grow up around affective experiences. "Motives are affectively toned associative networks arranged in a hierarchy of strength or importance within a given individual" (1969:43). The p_Achievement motive is embedded in the network, and is coded and measured through fantasy references, which a sub- ject makes in stories that he is asked to write or interpret. If a subject makes references to "doing something well, doing things better than someone else, or overcoming obstacles to achieve his goal, he is recorded as having a high p_Achievement score . . ." (1969:43). The point is to move the p_Achievement higher up in an individual's hierarchy of needs; how? By a specific type of educa- tional input. The basic concepts in the p_Achievement syndrome which is viewed as an "associative network" (1969:43) are "self-study," "goal-setting," and "interpersonal supports." These are also viewed as "inputs" or "themes" which are provided in the motiva- tional training course to the participants. Motives are "arranged in a hierarchy of strength or importance within a given individual." The function of the achieve- ment training was to move p_achievement upward in the individual's value hierarchy (1969:43). 49 "After the course, participants should think more often in terms of improving their business activities, take more successful moderate risks, use feedback, explore the environment, and so on" (1969:79). The results of these ventures would become visible in both changed behavior, and concrete outcomes, "such as unusual pay raises, promotions to jobs of higher entrepreneurial responsi- bility, increased profits, decreased costs, larger sales volume, and the like" (1969:79). Implementation of Educational Program for n Achievement In the education program undertaken by McClelland and his colleagues, the attempt was made to directly influence people in a community and to increase their p Achievement. "The ultimate test that p_Achievement is a key ingredient in economic growth must be an experiment aimed at altering it to see what the effects would be" (1969:36). The purpose of the study was to increase p_Achieve- ment in a group of businessmen by a specific type of education. The population chosen was not general but quite specific. The rationale for selecting businessmen was based on prior research that stated that the socio-economic background and p_Achievement of individuals are related--"individuals with a moderate level of education in the middle classes have the highest p_Achievement" (1969:31). It is people who have "certain dispositions, chiefly a high p_Ach," who are "likely to take advantage of economic oppor- tunities" (1969:5). People are differentially motivated and those 50 who are more motivated are more likely to be achievement oriented and consequently more likely to take advantage of opportunities and succeed. After a survey to obtain comparative statistics on several small cities in India three cities--Kakinada, Rajamundry, and Vellore--which fulfilled the researcher's criteria for the measure- ment of effectiveness of p_Achievement training were selected. Three groups of businessmen totalling 150 in number from the three cities were identified. One was the group provided training, another group from the same city did not receive any training, and a third group of businessmen from another city also served as a control group. From the third city, a similar control and experi- mental groups constituted part of the study. The rationale was that the first group would show significant increases in "entre- preneurial spirit" which would "help create a more 'go ahead' atmosphere for all businessmen in the city," and lead to a fall-out effect on the control group in the same city, while the third control group would show no changes at all either in p_Achievement or in economic growth, as they would not have received either training nor fall-out effect. Because of the withdrawal of substantial financial support of the project, the study took the form of a pilot project, and the assessment of the impact of the training on the general economy of the community was not feasible. They were able to obtain answers only to "what happens to the business activities of men after they have been exposed to achievement motivation training" (1969:107). 51 Men involved in industry, commerce and some professionals were the participants in the courses in achievement training. They were by the writers own account, quite well-to-do. The range at one end for several men totalled assets of "at least a million dollars in land, bank deposits, or cash. At the other extremes were several who earned as little as 1,500 rupees a year." But the latter had "sources from which they could raise capital if necessary" (1969:127). The study was conducted under the aegis of Small Industries Extension Training Institute in Hyderabad (SIET), an institute set up to help develop small industries and provide training (1969:98). The course content included a variety of inputs. They were described by the writers as constituting elements of the management training seminars conducted in the United States. The basic ele- ments were: the achievement syndrome, self-study, goal-setting, and interpersonal supports (1969:45). These themes were woven into the courses. Each was further sub-divided into separate terms and concepts and together they constituted the training inputs. For examples: the achievement syndrome included "fantasy," described as the ability "to recognize and produce achievement- related fantasies" (1969:45); "goal-setting," attempts to help the trainees "to define more precisely what goals they will set for themselves and how they will go about measuring progress toward these goals" (1969:66); "interpersonal supports" recognized the need for providing "warmth," the need for an appropriate "retreat 52 setting," and the need for group association was recognized as an important ingredient. The training lasted about 10-15 days, and the businessmen were provided training in groups averaging thirteen in number. The participants had to reside at SIET for the duration of the course. The educational program of psychological change in order to be effective had "to create a climate in which what is supposed to happen will happen" (1969:153). After the first course, a "Manual for Instructors" was written in which the ideal character- istics of the faculty member were described and his role vis-a-vis the trainee outlined. The attitude of the instructor toward the trainee is summarized as follows: You are a strong person, worthy of respect. You can make your own decisions, having obtained help and guidance from others. You can change and redirect your life if you want to badly enough. Don't believe those philosophers who say that you never can be anything but what you are. All we can do is give you some new techniques, discovered by psychological science, which will help you define your goals and find ways of achieving them (p. 160). On a personal, emotional, and social basis, the course was described as having a strong positive impact on the participants, — according to the evaluations provided by participants (p. 175). To examine the impact of the training program upon the business activity of the participants, a longterm assessment and evaluation had to be carried out. After completion of the course each participant was visited about every six months to see how he was progressing toward the goals he had set in the course. The aim 53 in fbllowing up on the business activity was to remind "the participants that they were being watched," that they were to con- sider themselves to be still "in training" and that they were responsible for comparing "their actual progress with the goals they had set for themselves" (p. 177). The businessmen formed an Entrepreneurs Association, but it functioned only as a place where people socialized. Immediate impact of the course was insignificant. Several months later, the major author visited the city to meet with the businessmen who had participated in the training course. By his own account, this visit functioned as an important morale booster. Besides creating "interest and curiosity" since they had never met the major author, but only heard about him, the visit, it was thought, "would strengthen individuals' faith that they could and should change" (p. 179). (The follow-up visits were to help reinforce the motiva- tion of participants. "Factual information" on business activity was obtained from the participants, but according to the authors, As the amount of factual information increased from successive visits, it became more and more evident that it did not provide a solid basis for evidence of changes in business activity levels (p. 196). Nevertheless, progress did occur. Frequent visits by several out- siders to evaluate the effectiveness of the training program were undertaken. 54 Assessment and Outcome of the Training in Motivation Program Follow-up visits, interviews with some of the participants, and statistical data measuring increased economic activity were obtained periodically after the completion of the training program. The aim was to discover the effects of p_AChievement on economic development of the various businesmen. Did training in need for achievement produce the appropriate values and attitudes necessary to produce economic development? At the individual level, some of the changes in attitudes, values and behaviors as a result of p_ Achievement training inputs described by the writers are: 1. More individuals stated that they were involved in planning new activities. (This finding had to be disregarded in evaluation, as it was difficult to separate out how much the individuals wanted "to tell the visitor that he was living up to his obligation to become active" [l969:l82]); 2. McClelland's visit several months after courses were conducted did much to "recommit individuals, both publicly and privately, to the goals they had set for themselves" (1969:180). It was considered a great reinforcer for the individuals as for the group of participants as a whole; 3. Some of the changes perceived by one evaluator were (a) there was a greater "perception of risk" on the individual's part, but without, however, "any change in the objective situation"; (b) the ability to view things in achievement terms was recognized. Achievement imagery that seemed to have some effect was one defined 55 as "proving oneself to oneself," but none of the other aspects of achievement imagery--"competition with others," "unique accomplish- ment," "long-term involvement," however, had any relevance for the participants; (c) nonetheless, they are perceived as having become "more imaginative" with respect to thinking about achievement and planning; (d) others who were enthusiastic during the training were less so later (1969:193-95). 4. A separate detailed sampling of businessmen was under- taken and the summary was that the men sampled worked harder after the course, some made new plans for starting businesses, but for many these did not work out, and they continued to expand their old business. The interviewer states that some of these undertakings involved "complex business and family, but these are not explored." 5. Impressive statistics are provided that display the effect of the training on the economic performance and entrepre- neurial activity of the businessmen. The measures of entrepre- neurial activity reported document "changes in activity, labor, capital, and output" (1969:214). In all these areas, the partici- pants in the courses showed significant improvements compared to two years before as well as to the control groups. However, there are differences in economy activities of the participants. The writers attempt to identify factors that con- tribute to change and those which do not in order to identify obstacles to change. In examining the social and cultural back- grounds of the "Changers" and the "Inactives,i such as caSte, age, education, religious beliefs, the conclusions drawn are that there 56 seem to be few consistent patterns of difference between the practices of the Changers and those of the Inactives in the areas of "Subordination, Dependence, Cast Rules, Religious Behavior, and Feminism" (1969:262). While "the Changers had made significant economic improve- ments . . . they do not appear to be different in their verbally expressed values." The conclusion reached is that For every highly modernized, sephisticated Changer who spoke to us in fluent English, there seemed to be a devout Hindu wearing a kurta or lungi, who spoke broken English haltingly, but who nevertheless had made observable and important improvements in his business after the course. Moreover, just as there were traditional, orthodox men who did not change, so also were there highly educated, Westernized men who made eloquent excuses for their inactivity (1969:263). Comparison of those who changed after the course and those who did not are therefore not related to traditional beliefs, values, and attitudes on the part of one or the other group. These do not inhibit people from entrepreneurial activity. Yet, in spite of the "negative results" the writers "feel that the Changers must be different, psychologically, from the Inactives . . . in deeper and more subtle ways than can be detected by value questionnaires (1969:268). The subtleties were obtained by administering a variety of clinical tests, such as the Semantic Differential Test, TAT, answers to "Who Am I?" The conclusions reached were that the dif- ferences between the changers and the inactives were in terms of "a styfle of describing" the goals." The former envisioned 57 "autonomous action," while the latter contemplated a "goal state" in their responses (1969:271-72). In order to evaluate individual differences in response to achievement motivation training, four in-depth cases of participants were conducted. Of these, three are considered "Changers," and one "Inactive." Some of the conclusions from the analysis of the life histories are: 1. There was no single aspect of achievement motivation training to which all favorable responses could be attributed. "Individuals seem to have responded positively to the training courses for different reasons" (1969:305). 2. The changes that did result cannot be described as having effected the "deep-seated transformation of the motivation of the participants. Rather, it appears that the courses affected individuals by accentuating, building upon, or focusing potential for entrepreneurial activity which was already there" (305). 3. The initial p_Achievement score obtained on each individual cannot "predict which men will become active after the course" (307). However, the conclusion is that there is "a good deal of latent entrepreneurial talent that is never put to use." But, a training program by providing "practical assistance, prestigious inspiration, and the increasing of a businessman's perceived probability of business success," can convert latent capacities and channel them into economic activity (1969:308). A more significant conclusion concerning the impact of achievement motivation training was that its effectiveness depends 58 not on the training or the educational input, but "in the partici- pant's situation." '"Men who changed after the course were those who had the most scope and opportunity to change--those who could con- trol their activities and thus realize their plans" (1969:250). Consequently, the achievement motivation training is most likely to succeed with those who are independent--owners or managers or their own business. With such men "with an opportunity to initiate changes in life--the effect of p_Achievement training are large and highly significant" (1969:311). It is also effective with those who are initially dissatisfied with a situation and feel that they can do something to solve a particular problem. Beyond these two differences, there were no significant differences in individual behaviors noted between the Changers and the Inactives as a result of the training. The influence of the situational elements is an obvious fact, but it did not occur to the researchers to include it within their explanatory framework, partly because as psychologists they were more interested in "the extent to which a man with increased motivation could make opportunities for himself" (312). They found that unless there is opportunity available into which an individual can channel his energies--p_Ach--it is futile to attempt to raise levels of p_Ach. In fact, they suggest "that increasing p_Ach when no opportunities exist will actually lead to less activity" (334). Nevertheless, in discussing the general role 0f psycho- logical education in development the authors state that the 59 constraints to economic development are neither external nor are they internal-~that is, there are neither institutional constraints operating to prevent men from achieving, nor are the attitudes and beliefs a hinderance to economic development. What is important, however, is that: . man develop a strong faith in himself as an origin or agent of change, as someone who can solve problems efficaciously on his own. If he believes in himself, if he is motivated to change things, then in: is undoubtedly an expert on how to carry out change within his social framework and within his traditional beliefs. The most effective strateQY. in other words, appears to be to change the man's self-image by direct instruction on this key point, and then to leave the rest to him (p. 349). Indirect methods in the form of better ways, advice and assistance neither strengthen "self-confidence" nor the individual's "con- viction" that he can solve problems. It seems far more effective to convince a man directly that he can accomplish what he wants, that he can become a change agent, and then trust him to find ways within his traditional culture of accomplishing his aims (p. 350). Transformation of adult self-image is an essential factor in development, and unlike traditional psychological thinking, adult motivation can be changed, through "achievement motivation training" (p. 350). The effectiveness of psychological education with adults (yields quicker results. unlike education of children, because "reason and understanding help a person change" (p. 356). "Adults are in a position to be agents, to test out new behaviors, to demon- strate to themselves that they are no longer pawns" (p. 256). 60 Adults have the freedom to act, and "they are also in a better position to put the changes into effect immediately" (p. 356). Mobilization of resources (in this case, motivation), is the best way to get plans implemented, to obtain results, to achieve targets (p. 369). Macroeconomic theory dealing with the behavior of firms specify only the optimum way for allocating resources between various factors in order to obtain optimal growth in profits and is not concerned with problems of resource mobiliza- tion. At most they specify what institutions and manpower, or human resources are needed to implement plans, and set targets for training. "Plans often fall far short of being realized because the motivational mechanisms necessary to implement them are not understood" (p. 370). McClelland argues against social determinism in social science which states that the individual "is a creature of tradition and economic and environmental circumstances beyond his control" (p. 377). The "unintended consequences" of deterministic analysis is "that they convince the people described that in fact they can do nothing to change their condition, that the environment must change first" (p. 377). . . man is not as predetermined in what he can do as social scientists and historians sometimes think. He has greater freedom to act, to change the structure of his response, and find opportunities in his environment than the traditional forms of social analysis would lead him to believe (p. 378). It is by gaining knowledge of oneself and from science that one can act and become the prime mover. "Knowledge is the new source of power. Somehow, by thoroughly understanding how we are determined, we gain the confidence to act so as to transcend determinism" (p. 378). 61 It is through confidence, conviction and understanding of oneself, and one's goals, and knowledge of one's competence that men acquire the power to shape their destiny (p. 378). CHAPTER IV ANALYSIS AND EVALUATION OF McCLELLAND'S TRAINING PROGRAM IN NEED ACHIEVEMENT Analysis of Theoretical Presuppositions First, some clarification of the use of psychological definitions of terms and concepts is in order. The concept of need as symbolized by the letter "pf creates a false "aura of the exact sciences" (Andreski, 1972:63). Further, the use of a single concept leads to confusing need as an objective criterion necessary for survival with subjective states of desire--likes, dislikes, inclinations. This particular dimension of the term "need" is left unspecified. For instance, an individual may desire something without necessarily needing it, or need something and yet have no desire for it. People may desire to consume food or accumulate wealth, or they may need clean air or pure drinking water. Beyond certain biologically determined needs--need for survival, protection, positive affect--most needs are objectively determined (Goldschmidt, 1959). Need for achievement as conceived by McClelland purports to provide for differences in economic activities of individuals by treating need as a particular inclination to achieve economically. However, the achievement motive, as a basic human urge or impulse, can be directed to a variety of ends--it should not be equated with 62 63 economic success alone. As Lalit Sen points out, It is more realistic to define achievement motivation in terms of specific dimensions such as ocpppational achieve- ment, religious achievement, commercial achievement, familial achievement, and so on (Lalit K. Sen, 1973:98). The real issue is not the presence or absence of desire to achieve, "but the problem of why, in a given society, this desire is canalized towards one goal rather than another" (Andreski, 1972:69). To say that Indians lack a desire to achieve and that the causes of poverty or slow economic progress is this lack, is to express ethno- centrism. 0n the other hand, to admit that Indians do have a desire to achieve but that they are pursuing other goals, embodies a value premise about the adequacy of one goal over another. This requires clarification. This is not to deny the relevance of psychological terms and concepts, since certain psychological factors may be crucial for understanding and explaining behavior. However, a single psychologi- cal denominator is difficult to come by, and inadequate for account- ing for differences in change between groups. Psychological terms may help explain differences between individuals. For example, the effect of child-rearing practices upon high and low motivation in individuals can be hypothesized and investigated by the use of biographical and cultural and historical accounts. McClelland attempts just such an enterprise in The Achieving Society_(1961). But McClelland does more than examine the influence of child-rearing practices on individual motive to achieve, he extrapolates on the "general place of psychological forces on social processes" (Eisenstadt, 1963:425). 64 There is an implicit assumption that the level of develop— ment (of non—stagnation) of a society in all spheres is connected both with the existence of p_achievement and, presumably, with economic advancement (1963:427). Sociological constraints on psychological motivation are left unexplored, except to be defined as child rearing or socialization practices (Aberle, 1961). The goal of p_Achievement training is economic development. While economists take the psychological characteristics necessary for development for granted, McClelland set out to educate indi- viduals to consciously modify their behaviors, to re-orient their "structure of responses," to develop "appropriate interests, strategies, time perspective and perceptions" (1969:25). in order to further economic success. The psychological ingredients in the rational economic model constitute his p_Achievement syndrome and through education he attempts to move these higher up in an individual's hierarchy of needs. McClelland argues that, while all people have the propensity to achieve, some people do not display it. Those who do not can be made to do so through training. The incentive to change, however,' has to come out of the individual's own desires. McClelland rejects external incentives and allocation of resources as inadequate. One is not sure of the role of the researcher and the training program devised by him. Is he manipulating the environment or the individual, or both, or is he teaching the individual to manipulate himself? The findings of the individual case studies were that no two individuals responded alike to the educational input. Those indi- viduals who responded positively to the training did so for different 65 reasons and it could not be determined if the change resulted in the "deep-seated transformation of the motivation of the participants" (1969:305). To move on from this quagmire of indeterminism, one is relieved to find that the differences in responses to p_Achievement training as measured by various economic indicators of growth in business enterprises two years later are the result of the partici- pants' "situation." If a man is the owner, or manager of his own business, "with an opportunity to initiate changes in life-~the effect of p_Ach training are large and highly significant" (1969: 311). Differential opportunities are an important factor in the levels of p_Achievement displayed. But, nonetheless, a strong sense of efficacy, faith in oneself, belief that one can change things, are considered crucial elements. McClelland reduces structural con- straints to differential opportunities and the problem is one of individual perception of opportunities. Perceptions can be trans- formed by means of education and training. It seems far more effective to convince a man directly that he can accomplish what he wants, that he can become a change agent, and then trust him to find ways within his traditional culture of accomplishing his aims (1969:350). Once men's awareness has been changed, it is assumed that changes in opportunities will follow. Differences in ownership, wealth, control over resources and the instruments of production, the realities of authority, power and control are all subsumed under differential opportunities. 66 John Kunkel attempts to correct McClelland's approach by using a behavioristic methodology (Kunkel, 1963; 1965; 1970). The problem of economic development, and the efforts to explain them "can be substantially reduced by the employment of a behavioral model of man" (1970:101). It does not require, theoretically, the manipula- tion of individuals or their internal states and it by-passes the issue of inferring internal states from overt behavior which is a major methodological difficulty in McClelland's framework (1970:97). McClelland postulates a variety of needs as components of a person's 'internal state', but this method of analysis involves inferences from behavior (e.g., the writing of stories based on TAT pictures) which are difficult to validate, in order to explain the data collected by McClelland and his associates. The striving for excellence, like any other behavior, is shaped through differential reinforcement and punishment (Kunkel, QSI, 1961:82). Behaviorist psychology based on "an operant conditioning approach" relys "neither on inferences concerning an 'internal state' that cannot be validated nor on causal inferences which cannot be checked through objective, replicable procedures" (Kunkel, 1963: 74). The basic premise of the behaviorist model is that behavior is learned and acquired and can be changed. The prerequisites of social and economic change are not changes in attitudes, values and person- ality of actors, according to Kunkel, but changes in behavior. Since even the psychological approach infers the former states from observation of behaviors, attempts at change must focus on behavior. The behavioral model of man leads to the conclusion that, if behavior is to be changed, changes must first occur in the reinforcing stimuli, in their presentation and schedule, and in the discriminative stimuli (Kunkel, 1965:267). 67 It is the social structure which affects behavior, and it is viewed by Kunkel as "the continuously operating determination of reinforcing and discriminative stimuli . . ." (1965:276). Behavior is shaped by the arrangements of rewards and punishments. The terms and concepts used in a behaviorist model are those which are taken from a laboratory situation. While these are acceptable for describing and changing the behavior of an individual, to apply them as characteristics of the social structure of the environment is to narrow them to that of a laboratory situation. ‘Still, Kunkel holds to a somewhat mechanistic conception of the components of social structure. The most important proposition of the behavioral perspective, according to Kunkel is: "behavior is replicated when contingencies remain the same, and behavior is changed when contingencies are altered" (1970:285). Once again, issues of political power, control over resources, decisions con- cerning allocation are narrowed down and reduced to a re-arrangement of contingencies. There is the admission that action oriented programs based on operant principles cannot work as they lack control over existing reinforcers and the less control of the environment a planner or change agent has, the less is the likelihood of behavior change (Kunkel, 1965:276). Furthermore, behavior modification cannot be generalized from the individual to large scale programs of change. Although Kunkel recognizes that in the analysis of social change a number of variables need to be considered, economic develop- ment requires certain "behavioral prerequisites" on the part of the 68 individual. Those prerequisites include: The saving of money, the investment of savings, risk- taking, economic innovation, the ability to wait for returns on investments, abandoning the land, selling one's labour, working in factories, buying food products, hiring people on the basis of competence rather than affinity, etc. (Kunkel, 1965:275). The societal counterparts are: "rationality, functional specificity, a stable government" (1965:276). Structural factors are defined either by the use of terminology of the experimental laboratory situation, or by the use of abstract, ideal-typical terms and con- cepts. Underlying the "prerequisites" is an ethnocentric valuation of what is desirable. The list of behavioral and institutional pre- requisites that social scientists advocating a transformation of individual personality consider necessary for social change are usually: Drawn on the basis of the Protestant experience. Since the Protestant case is the only 'successful' example, the necessity of replicating this model has its own temptation as well as its own limits (Gupta, 1971:81). The tendency is to dichotomize developed and underdeveloped societies along a number of variables which are abstract, scientific, and presumably neutral, and supposedly devoid of value judgments. Far from being neutral, there is an acceptance of "the ultimate life goals of industrial civilization: work and acquisition of wealth as ends in themselves" (Weisskopf, 1950:329). These are justified, on the one hand, by the use of the rational economic model, and on the other, as a "natural" result of man's own needs and desires (1950: 319). "The value-attitudes of industrial society are included in the basic psychological assumptions of economic theory" (Weisskopf, 1950: 69 329). Within the individualistic and psychological framework that McClelland utilizes in his training program for p_Achievement there is an attempt to harmonize the motives, intentions, desires and interests of individuals to those of an industrial society. Another problem becomes evident in McClelland's attempt to reconcile the ends of economic development with those of individual self-interest. Within economics, a harmony between self-interest on the one hand and the common good on the other is assumed. Inherent in economic thought is a ". . . psychocultural attempt to bridge the gap between the requirements of the economic value complex and an altruistic, socially co-operative ethic" (Weisskopf, 1951: 199). The rational economic model functions under an aura of scientific neutrality, based on the assumption that individuals are by nature acquisitive--that "people just follow the pleasure principle or their egoistic instincts" (Weisskopf, 1951:199). Although "the secularization of economics resulted in its conscious emancipation from ethics" (Weisskopf, 1951:197), the necessity for a social ethic and altruism had to be justified by the introduction of a new economic value complex. Morally, it was considered reprehensible to pursue one's self-interest, consequently, it had to be demonstrated that self-interest leads to social welfare. . . . although it was felt to be immoral for the indi- vidual, it is moral from the view-point of the whole. The conflict between the aims of the individual and of society has been implicitly and explicitly a central theme of economic thought . . . attempts were made to eliminate it . the idea of the harmony of interests, the idea of maximization of total utility, social welfare, total satisfaction, the concept of equilibrium, etc., have been used for this purpose (Weisskopf, 1951:198). 70 The psychological individualistic approach utilized by McClelland is an attempt to propogate and bolster the rational economic model. While he accepts the axiom of the rational economic model and endeavours to make it causally more effective by the intro- duction of g_Achievement factor as a variable in furthering economic ends, he recognizes the peeg_for a social and altruistic ethic. Consequently, while g_Achievement is conceived as an individual virtue, an individual must learn to "do a better job and get more satisfaction out of life," and he must "find a better way of getting a job done" (McClelland, 1966:32-33). g Achievement is also seen as a social virtue; it must help further the cause of "larger social significance," to do something for the common good. In "ideal psychological terms" p_Achievement is a "personal" and a "social virtue? (1966:36). "The psychological elements essential to economic success are . . . the gegjre_to prove oneself better than others and the peeg_to promote the common good" (McClelland, 1966:38; emphasis added). The training in p_Achievement must lead to socially useful activities or projects. What is required is to develop in individuals the desire ". . . to do something not just for themselves but for Kakinada, for India, and possibly even for the whole world of stagnant communities like theirs (1966:35). N_Achievement is the key element in this conversion. The solution to lack of p_Achievement in a popula- tion is training. "By direct training, we can apparently infect the people who need it with both 9 Ach and a sense of public responsi;' bility" (1966:39). 71 The extrapolation from the individual to society, from self- interest to the social good, in McClelland's analysis, occurs through psychological education, by gaining knowledge of oneself one can shape one's destiny (see Chapter II). From an educational technique for motivating individuals for economic growth, the p_Achievement syndrome takes on the character of social-cultural transformation. This is done through the introduction of an altruistic ethic into the rational economic model which pro- fesses ethical neutrality. Economists view the harmony of interests as maintained by an "invisible hand"; although some have begun to argue that "the free play of market forces will pg; maximize social welfare," and that the State must "intervene repeatedly before we can feel even reasonably sure that the profit makers promote society's good as well as their own" (Rivett, 1959:7; see also Galbraith, 1973; Weisskopf, 1950, 1951). McClelland, on the other hand, not only assumes a unity of purpose between individual and society, but is confident that it can be guaranteed through psychological education. Economic behavior which is good for the individual is considered good for society. A consistency between "private calculus" and the "social calculus" is assumed (Blaugh, 1970). Adequacy_of Data and Its Empirical Validity According to McClelland "a minor economic revolution" was in the making in the town from which the businessmen were recruited for training in g_Achievement, the result of "an idea, the motive, the spark, the impulse, that seems to be necessary to set such a process 72 in motion" (1966:35). He hypothesizes that these businessmen can have a far-reaching effect on the economy of the town ". . . because these businessmen control most of the institutions that matter in the town: the banks, the cinemas, the shops, the foundaries, the mills" (1966: 35). He does not appear to recognize the significance of this control, except to state that the availability of opportunities is essential if g_Achievement training is to be effective. It may be possible to measure p_Achievement of individuals, although McClelland and his colleagues doubt if they were able to measure or change "deep-seated motivations." They have not, however, established the case that it is high levels of measured "need achieve- ment" which lead to economic growth; nor that the proVision of need achievement training increases the economic capabilities and partici- pation of individuals and leads to general economic development. In the training provided to the businessmen a variety of other devices were used. Well-known business leaders were invited to participate. Government officials who had authority to grant licenses became familiar with the group of businessmen and prestige and status appeals were used to boost morale and reinforce motivation. The effect of these factors on the economic growth of the groups is not measured. Another study of need achievement undertaken by Ashis Nandy, in a Calcutta suburb, adds some other dimensions to the study of this psychological characteristic of individuals (Singer, 1973). Mandy examined the distribution of p_Achievement between entrepreneurs and non-entrepreneurs. But, instead of adopting the approach that "high 73 entrepreneurial performance is mainly a function of high p_Achievement level," a la McClelland, Nandy examined the link between entrepre- neurial activity and the community support system (1973:168). There are four elements involved in his analysis: The psychological prerequisites which the economy sets for entrepreneurial success, the cultural grid which tends to screen persons fulfilling these prerequisites for entre- preneurship, the status and meaning which the community gives to those gravitating towards entrepreneurship because of their 'inner push,‘ and the community's structurally and psychologically determined threshold of motivation for entry into enterprise . . . (1973:169). This was a case study of a group of entrepreneurs belonging to the Mahisya caste which is historically and traditionally an agricultural caste ”relatively less educated, less urbanized, low-status . . . they constitute a traditional business community and apparently have little group experience in trade or commerce" (1973:170). They are, however, the only Bengali community who have entered into entrepre- neurial activity and made a success of it since the post-Independence period (1973:170). A comparable group of entrepreneurs and non- entrepreneurs belonging to the Mahisya caste and the upper castes were drawn for analysis and comparison. The type of data obtained were p_Achievement scores, and a scale of entrepreneurial competence (1973:171). The findings indi- cated that the Mahisyas had a lower level of p_Achievement than the upper caste groups. This might have been due to the fact that Mahisyas had been in entrepreneurial activities longer. They have "highly institutionalized channels through which the ambitions and skilled workers among them could enter and survive in business with the help of other Mahisyas," whereas the upper caste entrepreneurs 74 are deviants from their community. Nandy's conclusion was that "there is no one-to-one relationship between higher achievement motive and community success in enterprise" (1973:174). A finding which is con- tradictory to McClelland's own was that the more enterprising Mahisyas community "depends less on p_achievement to push its members into enterprise." It was the upper caste individual who, lacking community support, had to "depend more on the internal incentive of achievement need" (1973:174). For Nandy, "there is no significant relationship between entrepreneurial performance and need in either of the caste groups." While entry and survival into business may depend on such a need, "greater success and competence within it" do not require high p_Achievement (1973:175). The notion of p_Achievement as used by McClelland tends to compress or coalesce assignment of rewards and recruitment into entrepreneurial roles with individual motivation (Frank, 1967:46-47). A separation of each of the concepts points to the variability of the achievement motive relative to rewards and recruitment. To obtain rewards within roles, as the Nandy study shows, it may or may not be necessary to display high achievement motivation, as McClelland would have us believe. Individual achievement motivation is confused with "social role assignment and reward" (Frank, 1967:7). In McClelland's view, it is not the social structure, nor is it "reward in sbcial roles based on achievement . . . but only a high degree of individual motivation or need for achievement" which is the source of develop- ment (Frank, 1967:47). 75 The criteria of expansion and growth of entrepreneurial activity, which is said to co-vary with p_Achievement, in the Nandy study is shown to be complicated as a result of other factors, which in themselves may vary from area to area. These factors include "the state of the economy at a particular point in time," labour laws and trade union activities, in other words, "the entrepreneurial environ- ment" (Nandy, 1973:176-177). Both psychological and non-psychological factors have to be considered. In fact, as Singer in his intro- ductory remarks states, Nandy's conclusions point to: . . . social and cultural psychology rather than individual psychology. The functional equivalents of the "spirit of capitalism" and a "Protestant ethic" in Howrah may be a ppm? mgpjty_"spirit" and "ethos" among the Mahisyas, and an individualistic ethos among the members of upper castes who go into business and industry (Singer, l973:7). It becomes clear from McClelland's work that abstract, rigid criteria drawn from the Western context not only are inadequate, theoretically, but begin to lose whatever validity they have as empirical concepts. It should not be supposed, either, that achieve- ment motivation is a particular outgrowth of the Protestant ethic, nor that only individuals who belong to such cultures are socialized to display it. There is enough evidence to the contrary to disprove that (Singer, 1972, 1972, 1966; Goheen, Srinivas, Karve, and Singer, 1958). Although McClelland states that in order to have moderniza- tion and economic growth it is not necessary to overthrow all of traditional culture, he does base social change on the flowering of a particular personality type. But, as Singer points out, "it requires much more than a personality type or a social ethic to develop industrial capitalism . . ." (1973:286). Secondly, it is an 76 expression of an ethnocentric bias to state that achievement motiva- tion leads to economic achievement. But, McClelland's concern is only with establishing a relationship between p_Achievement as a psycho- logical characteristic and economic development. In attempting to provide empirical studies of economic development and social change which have been undertaken with some success, McClelland refers to the People's Republic of China (McClelland, 1963). Examining popular children's literature for achievement imagery, McClelland found that children's tales from Mainland China showed greater motivational concern as compared to China-Taiwan. The influence of the United States on the latter, according to McClelland, although great, has been more directed toward material and techno- logical change rather than to ideology. The Communists, on the other hand, are considered to be more ideologically oriented and they have been "more successful in moving the Chinese toward the psychological preconditions for a 'modern' technical and social order than Western democratic ideology," although McClelland recognizes that the former has a strong authoritarian climate "which can scarcely be called 'modern'" (1963:17). McClelland's conclusions are that it is pgt_the material arrangements or the environment which leads to changes in men's ideas and throughts, but is the other way around: "Ideas which succeed in capturing the minds of men shape institutions which in turn change the material environment" (1963:18). American social scientists, he argues, must "stress the importance of changing values or motiva- tional concerns" (1963:18). 77 The shortcomings of McClelland's analysis are cogently summed up by Frank: They (the Chinese) receive no credit for following the teachings of Marx or other social scientists, the validity of whose theory McClelland denies; no credit for changing any economic, social or political structure, the need for which change McClelland denies; nor any credit for making a revolution, which McClelland does not deem worthy of mention. Instead, they receive credit for realizing and putting into practice the truth that ideas and p_Achieve- ment promote economic development: The Chinese are achieving faster economic development than the Indians, McClelland points out. On the basis of what economic, social, and political structure, he doesn't say . . . (Frank, 1967: 52). The view that social and economic changes in China are caused by a particular ideology is simplistic, according to another writer, because it fails to take into consideration the socio-cultural system-~the dialectics of Chinese traditions as it interacts with patterns of change--and the concrete and specific conditions which lead to individual and institutional modernization (Gupta, 1971). The issues in social change that confront all societies are more than "internal transformations" of individuals. The problems that societies face and have to solve involve both a reworking of ideas and a reconstruction of on-going social life. The process of social change and modernization should be examined as strategies which different societies have worked out in order to cope with change (Singer, 1972: 406). The notion that choice is between change and modernization, on the one hand, and remaining static and tradition-bound on the other, is merely an abstract construction of ideal-types, although writers have tended to assume that they are equivalent to reality. 78 Policy Implications What are some of the conclusions that can be extrapolated for policy-makers and planners from McClelland's specific educational strategy, and the general development program that he offers? There are two issues here. One has to do with the relationship between p_Achievement training and general, formal education. The other involves the focus on entrepreneurs and innovators, and the implica- tions for social change. By extrapolating from McClelland's study of a particular educational approach to development, some implications for the general educational situation can be drawn, providing it can be assumed that formal education aims at inculcating similar types of changes--behavioral and psychological and motivational--as are expressed in McClelland's notion of the "achievement syndrome." That is, "doing something well," or "doing something better“ with some standard of excellence, by means of "self-study," "goal setting," and "interpersonal support," may be considered standard criteria of any educational enterprise. N_Achievement can be measured, according to McClelland. So can educational inputs and learning by means of IQ and intelligence and other types of tests. The concern in drawing a parallel between formal education and McClelland's p_Achievement training is not simply to emphasize points of similarities, but to raise a question concerning the purpose of'gpy_educational input. The educational input that McClelland provided to the group of businessmen was tailored to their needs. In fact, McClelland 79 states that although the technique was used with "unmotivated high school boys," g_Achievement training is particularly suited to those in business, or in a position to plan to go into business (1969:351). One side effect of the training program in India was that "achievement motivation for underachieving high-school students" is being undertaken on an extensive scale in India (1969:451). If this means introducing such techniques of the achievement syndrome as goal setting, self study, and interpersonal support into the class- room environment, from an intrinsically educational point of view, .this can be looked upon as an improvement in practice. But the leap from training in motivation to its contribution to economic develop- ment is laden with impediments which are more than psychological. As McClelland himself indicates, differential opportunity and individual perception of one's situation determine the extent to which p_Achievement training can be effective. It follows, therefore, that for social change and economic development to occur, either individuals have to be dissatisfied with their present situation or else they have to have control and management over their own productive activities. To take McClelland's conclusions that the analysis of the structure of available oppor- tunities and personal dissatisfaction are important criteria before g_Achievement can make a difference in the individual achievement, one brief example from India will suffice to highlight both issues. Kerala is the state in India with the highest rate of literacy. The all-India literacy rate is 29 per cent; Kerala has 66 per cent of its male and 53 per cent of its female population 80 literate (Apte, 1975:1041), but Kerala also faces an acute problem of educated unemployed. Unemployment among professionally and technically qualified persons has reached serious proportions. As on December 31, 1972 there were 654 medical graduates and 2,014 engineering graduates seeking employment through employment exchanges. In addition, there were 4,163 engineering diploma-holders and 11,540 ITI certificate- holders among the job-seekers . . . . The seriousness of the situation is brought out by the fact that when applications were invited for 14,000 jobs under the special employment programme in June 1973, the office of Kerala Public Service Commission was flooded with nearly 6 lakh applications in a matter of days (Apte, 1975:1041). This problem is further aggravated by the fact that as more and more individuals migrate to other states in search of jobs, the state of Kerala loses the social and economic benefits from its investment in education. If this unemployed group of educated persons were also to receive a psychological education in p_ Achievement without institutional channels for their absorption, their high motivation potential might be directed into disruptive and "revolutionary activities" (Eisenstadt, 1963:429). McClelland, however, is not interested in providing p_ Achievement training to the masses of educated or uneducated. His concern is to mobilize the scarce high p_Achievement resources of the developing countries, especially the entrepreneurial cadres. The implications of his study are that business entrepreneurs and their contribution to economic development is significant enough to have an effect on the total economy. But, as Frank points out, there is increasing evidence to the contrary concerning the suppOSed role played by the entrepreneur, not only in the underdeveloped 81 countries, but in the developed countries as well (Frank, 1967:48). Besides, entrepreneurs of the type examined by McClelland constitute only a small percent of the total population. Indian workers employed in modern industry constitute only three percent of the population (Lipton, 1968:130). Programs of social change and development which focus on groups of entrepreneurs and innovators have been encouraged and undertaken by economists and development planners who are concerned with rapid economic growth. Within the area of education itself, this has led to an emphasis on formal education, especially higher education, to the neglect of free, compulsory, universal primary education (Laska, 1968); and in the area of economic development, especially agriculture, the pages of Economic and Political Weekly_ are replete with statistics, data, and information on the second generation problems of the Green Revolution as they become visible in skewed employment wages, and income distribution, as both inputs and profits flow to the "innovators." The masses of small farmers, tenants, and landless labourers are caught in a cycle of unredeeming poverty. To apply McClelland's framework to the situation of the poor, the following explanation becomes apparent: if attempts to change the "structure of responses" of the poor were made they would most likely be ineffective since the people lack opportunities to put the newly gained p_Achievement to useful purpose, and besides, "increasing p_Ach when no opportunities exist will actually lead to less activity" (1969:334). 82 A psychological explanation provided by some social scientists for the paradoxical situation of the poor is described as a "cycle of poverty" syndrome. The notion of "poverty cycle" is explained as follows: Limited income results in poverty; poverty somehow creates a physical and cultural environment that suppresses the poor's aspirations, motivation, and capacity to achieve; without these, the poor do not acquire sufficient education, resulting in limited earning potential; and with little earning potential, there are limited earning opportunities, hence poverty is inevitable (Turner, 1972:81). The tendency in such an analysis is to ignore and "underemphasize the broader cultural and institutional forces within which this cycle operates" (1972:81; Valentine, 1968) and to blame the poor for the situation they happen to be in. Moreover, by providing a "scientific explanation" for the problem, the situation becomes acceptable and the responsibility for it conveniently narrowed down to the individual. McClelland's solution to the problems of development is to center official encouragement and support on the more enterprising classes or groups both in industry and agriculture. Psychological education can be effective only with the "haves," and not with the "have-nots." The effects of a development strategy that by design or by default provides benefits to the "haves" in the hope that they will in turn contribute to the common good is to create further imbalances and inequalities. McClelland ostensibly attempts to take the human factor into account in considerations of social change and development. He 83 rejects models of development that focus on capital and resource allocation or those which advocate a restructuring of environmental factors as inadequate. However, in the last analysis, the goals which McClelland's high achievers are supposedly trained to pursue are those dictated by such models of development. Over and above his concerns with the individual in social change is a vulgarized form of positivism (see Murphy, 1971, for a discussion of psycho- logical assumptions underlying structural functionalism; Wrong, 1961, for the "oversocialized view of man"). Recently, several social scientists from India have begun to point out the limitations of the models of development that have been adopted in India. These models "are more suited to countries faced not by large backlogs of unemployment but rather a scarcity of hands" (Kothari, 1972:1543). Another writer indicates that the one- dimensional policy of production and economic growth based on the assumption that production and distribution are separate and that the former would guarantee the latter has not been substantiated by reality. Not only has there been no equalization of income--"4O per cent in rural and 50 per cent in urban areas are living below the 'poverty line,'" unemployment, which the rapid growth model hoped to solve, continues to grow. The modern sector cannot adequately employ the growing population (Kothari, 1972:1542). The consequences of the use of the model of modernization based on techno-economic transformation have been that there is an overriding concern to keep up with the affluent countries. It has led to a neglect of the real and immediate problems facing Indian 84 society. It has created socioeconomic cleavages between urban and rural areas. The model has produced distorted priorities in alloca- tion of resources and choice of technologies (Kothari, 1972:1545). The "new model" that Kothari outlines is in essence an old one. In fact he states: Gandhi put his finger on the most crucial dimension of moving towards a just social order when he called for a limitation of wants on the part of affluent sections of the people and warned his countrymen against falling prey to an industrial machine . . . . Today his insights are even more relevant than when he lived. If we are to remove garabi [poverty], have justice among our pe0ple and put an end to exploitation, the present norm of a high consumption ethic must give place to one that limits the needless expansion of wants . . . (Kothari, 1972:1549). The next chapter explores the Gandhian approach in detail. CHAPTER V GANDHIAN SCHEME OF BASIC EDUCATION T0 TRANSFORM INDIVIDUALS AND RECONSTRUCT SOCIETY Introduction A major problem of social science in general and the Indian social scientists in particular--one that has been the source of much criticism 1ately--has been their Western orientation (Joshi, 1970; Srinivas, 1975). According to Joshi, the growth of social science in the developing countries ". . . has occurred not in response to endogenous compulsions but as a result of exogenous implantation" (1970:139). Srinivas, in an article on social science research in India, says that there is in India a deep division between the "theoretician-analyst" and the "fact-gatherer." This division is further exacerbated by the use of Western "models, concepts, and even empirical experience from Europe, USA, USSR or China" (1975:1389). This has contributed to biases in perception concerning the direction, rate, and type of change that India should take. Social science cannot but be relativistic and consequently it must be integral to the social, political, and economic realities in which it is conducted. A social scientist in India must gain an understanding of the Indian social situation first, before he can "contribute to the greater universalism" of his discipline (Srinivas, 1975:1389). 85 86 Indian social scientists, according to Joshi and Srinivas, have neglected Gandhi's perceptions and analysis of Indian society, and the solutions that he sought to problems facing Indian society. Srinivas comments that: One wonders whether Gandhi's stressing of the importance of living in the villages to understand the conditions and problems of villagers had had any effect on the elite (Srinivas, 1975:1387). It is the indigenous nature of Gandhi's thought and ideas which distinguishes him. He provided an alternative perception of the Indian situation in the realms of politics, economics and culture. I shall discuss Gandhi's educational program as one indigenous alternative, examine its implementation in the form of Basic Education, and outline the outcomes and results which ensued. In the next chapter an analysis ofthe ideological foundations of his approach and the individualistic and psychological prescriptions that were embedded in it will be explored. A discussion of his perceptions and insights into the social, cultural, and economic problems of India will be presented. Goals, Objectives, and Principles Of Basic EdUcation Gandhi's ideas encompass politics, religion, economics, and social concerns. He visualized a world free from exploitation and violence. The dilemma of present-day societies, both democratic and socialist, is that exploitation in one form or another--social, political, economic--exists in both. In the context of India, Gandhi sought to overcome exploitation by "a new synthesis." 87 Exploitation of the poor by the rich cannot be overcome, according to Gandhi, "as long as it reigns supreme in the human mind." Gandhi sought "to liquidate it at the very source, through proper educa- tion“ (Gupta, 1970:52). It was a non-violent and non-exploitative society that Gandhi sought to create, a society in which each man would seek 13g h through the ideal means of Non-violence and Love. These values are viewed as inherent in human nature but can be realized through training. It is their pursuit which can lead to the all- around development of individual personality (Gupta, 1970:53). Gandhi's vision of India was that of a "nation with a special 'spiritual' vocation" (Rudolph and Rudolph, 1967:216). His secular views on Indian society parallel the other-wordly aspects of high thought. He visualized an India of self-sufficient autonomous village communities, in which "each would work for all and all for each," and service would be the "motive force" (Salamatullah, 1970: 21-22). Gandhi's ideal was . . . to revitalize the village community economically and morally, transforming it into a viable and attractive alternative to urban and machine civilization. By freeing men from the dehumanizing tyranny of artificial wants and the production required to satisfy them . . . (Rudolph and Rudolph, 1967:217). The ideals which Gandhi sought to achieve also involved a realistic appreciation of the problems of Indian society. By call- ing for a restructuring of the goals of education he sought not only to transform education, but to highlight the evils in the general social, cultural, and economic arrangements, and to attempt 88 to harness education to solve socio-economic problems of rural poverty, urban-rural imbalances and mass unemployment. It is difficult to separate Gandhi's views concerning educa- tion and develOpment of individual personality from his views con- cerning the direction in which Indian society should move. More- over, education is assigned a significant function in this development. It is an instrument for furthering individual and social goals. At the individual level, the aim of education is to draw out the best in man, to create suitable conditions for the realization of potentialities in man (Salamatullah, 1970; Gupta, 1970). By education, I mean an all-round drawing out of the best in child and man--body, mind, and spirit. Literacy is not the end of education, not even the beginning. It is only one of the means whereby men and women can be educated. Literacy in itself is no education. I would therefore begin the child's education by teaching it a useful handicraft . . . I hold that the highest development of the mind and soul is possible under such a system of education. Only handi- crafts have to be taught, nor merely mechanically as is done today, but scientifically, i.e., the child should know the why and wherefore of every process (Gandhi, 1962:263-64). Gandhi was for free compulsory education at the primary level, but emphasized the integration of vocations into education. Social reconstruction, both rural and urban, could occur only when educa- tion was integrated with the needs and requirements of the villages. Education was to be imparted through village crafts. Such an educa- tional medium would be: . . the spearhead of a silent social revolution fraught with the most far-reaching consequences . . . . It will check the progressive decay of our villages and lay the foundation of a juster social order in which there is no unnatural division between the "haves" and the "have-nots" 89 and everybody is assured of a living wage and the right to freedom. And all this would be accomplished without the horrors of a bloody class-war or a colossal capital expenditure such as would be involved in the mechanization of a vast continent like India (Gandhi, 1962:275). The aim of education—-"the all round development of the individual"-- could be achieved by imparting it through a village craft. If all education were woven around a craft, it would provide work which was simple and easily available and would require little training. The craft would be closer to the needs of the masses and yet be pro- ductive. The product would be "economically remunerative so as to defray the recurring cost of education; and it would lead to self- sufficiency of education (Kripalani, 1957:4-7). "To Gandhiji, it was not a matter of expediency but a matter of conviction that education must be self-sufficient“ (Salamatullah, 1970:22). The rural self-sufficiency to be obtained through craft-centered work was viewed as a solution to the socio-economic problems of migration, rural poverty, and mass unemployment. The concept and idea of work was an integral element in the develOpment of Gandhi's thoughts on education. The disease of the masses is not want of money so much as want of work. Labour is money. He who provides dignified labour for the millions in their cottages, pro- vides food and clothing (Avinashlingam, 1964:50 [quote of Gandhi's from Economics of Khadi:129]). The recognition of financial constraints on the provision of universal education led Gandhi to formulate work as an important element of education. Work which could be utilized in the learning and doing of a continuous craft which, in its turn, is capable of creating wealth, capable of being measured in terms of money . . . the only practical 90 and possible way of making education available to all is to make students earn through their work and help maintain the school (Avinashlingam, 1964:61). The introduction of economic calculations into education Gandhi viewed to be neither out of place nor "sordid." True economics never militates against the highest ethical standard, just as all true ethics to be worth its name must at the same time be also good economics. An economics that inculcates Mammon worship and enables the strong to amass wealth at the expense of the weak, is a false and dismal science . . . . True economics, on the other hand, stands for social justice, it promotes the good of all equally including the weakest and is indis- pensable for decent life (Gandhi, 1962:273). Service and uplift of the community were the important aims of educa- tion. These were to be achieved through the commitment of people to those aims, by sticking to them “with undivided loyalty." Failures arise only when "the workers are not loyal to their aims or only half-hearted in carrying them out“ (Gandhi, 1962:152). Teachers are admonished to "have faith and the spirit of sacrifice" and to communicate this to the students: Our students should be men who will work for the stabilization and revitalization of our rural civilization. They would study the needs of the villagers, try to remove the defects they may discover in them and train their children to become good farmers and good villagers . . . . Thus, as long as we do not set about to make a radical change in the form and content of the education now going on in the cities, we cannot fulfill one of the important aims . . . (1962:150). Gandhi conceived the eradication of untouchability and the introduction of charka (spinning wheel) as two of "the most essential ingredients" of education (1962:96). The removal of untouchability would lead to social and cultural transformation, and the learning of handicrafts, such as spinning, was viewed as an economic 91 necessity. As Beteille points out, Harijans (the name given to untouchable castes by Gandhi; meaning literally children of Hari or God) generally perform manual work, and in the popular mind manual occupations and low-caste status are associated (Beteille, 1969:91). Gandhi was attempting to break down age old occupational and social barriers through the schools. The argument he used was that work and intellectual knowledge should not be separated. It is for the schools to demonstrate that "there is no conflict between the two" (Gandhi, 1962:196). Gandhi's educational philosophy held that the introduction of manual work into education would give it dignity and respect- ability. Education would inculcate values of dignity of labor. The causes of poverty were considered to be a "want of faith in ourselves," and "due partly to our laziness and want of application and partly to labelling manual work inferior and relegating it to the lower castes" (Avinashlingam, 1964:59). The underlying emphasis was on "sacrifice, simplicity, and identification with the masses" (Kripalani, l957z9). A combination of economic necessity and moral reformation underlay the scheme of Basic Education devised by Gandhi. On the one hand was the idea of economic self-sufficiency, the need for education to pay for itself, while at the same time providing and developing the productive and social capacities of individuals. Through learning craft work, students would acquire both technical skills of production, and intellectual growth through mastering the scientific processes of production. Knowledge would be functional 92 and useful. The "educative value of manual work" became a funda- mental principle (Avinashilingam, 1964:76). Education would fulfill both the needs of society and those of individuals, by cultivating "virtues like cooperation, mutual understanding, service, freedom and discipline . . ." (Salamatullah, 1970:23). Gandhi's educational ideas are interrelated with his economic, social, political, and religious ideas. There is not only an intimate relation between the creed and the programmes but the programmes are organically interrelated and inter- connected. . . . They cannot be dissected or subdivided arbitrarily and one part accepted and the other part rejected. The programmes are to be accepted in their interrelation and are not to be cut off from their roots in basic principles of the creed (Kriplani, 1957:84-58; see also Joshi, 1970 and Rivett, 1959). Implementation of Basic Education Gandhi's ideas on education were presented formally at a conference of well-known Indian educators and political leaders in 1937. A committee was formed and his ideas endorsed in the form of resolutions. Briefly stated these were: free compulsory education for seven years, through the mother-tongue, centering around some form of manual, productive work which took into account both the abilities of the child and the surrounding environment, with the process of education to be self-supporting (Avinashilingam, 1964:61; and Ganchi, 1962:26). Basic Education as set forth by Gandhi, was modified-- especially his ideas concerning economic self-sufficiency of educa- tion underwent some change. Even so, Basic Education was implemented both by government and private institutions, some specifically set up 93 for the purpose. During the implementation, a reformulation and reinterpretation of both theory and practice of Basic Education con- tinued. The controversy and discussion it generated was carried forward on one side by the true believers and on the other by the skeptics. The elements of Basic Education which were accepted as viable for universal practice were the moral values of education, and ideas concerning the ideal personality; as well as the concept of education and transformation of the individual through inculcation of specific social values--dignity of labour, social awareness, responsibility, cleanliness, c00peration, community spirit as desirable values--and the creation of individual personal character- istics of fearlessness, truth, non-violence, detachment, self- control, non-possession, humility, cheerfulness, calmness, non-self seeking (Ramji, 1970:26-27). While the concept of self is an integral part of Gandhi's thought, educationists and social scientists and those assigned the task of implementation of Basic Education have given the development and growth of attitudes and values and other components of personality an important place in Basic Education. The techniques of teaching advocated were con- sonant with the best of the education theory existing at the time-- activity learning, learning through doing, skills that required both mental and physical manipulation. Orientation around a craft was thought to provide self-expression, and the use of all faculties (Avinashilingam, 1964:69). 94 The economic value of education, that is, self-sufficiency as a criteria inherent in education, however, was modified. Some of the views on the subject ranged from concerns that it would lead to commercialization of education, to visions of abuses of child labour. It is somewhat of an enigma that Gandhi , who advocated the inculca- tion of altruistic values through education, should have been con- cerned with the economic values of education—~its efficiency and cost-benefits. As one writer points out, "The self-supporting part should be the logical corollary of the fact that the pupil has learnt the use of everyone of his faculties“ (Avinashilingam, 1964: 69). Besides, there are two integral elements in his thought which help explain the emphasis on the economic value of education. First, Gandhi's moral and social philosophy were integrated and organically conceived, the neglect of one or the other provides only a partial answer. Second, the answers that Gandhi sought were to some very basic and fundamental problems facing Indian society. These were poverty of the masses, the rural-urban dichotomies, and“ endemic unemployment (Joshi, 1970; and Rivett, 1959). In this con- text, the economic criteria had to be an integral element of moral education if education was to help solve some of the problems. The revolutionary implications of economic self-sufficiency of education and through education of rural society were perhaps not fully compre- hended by the educational and political elite; in any case, they were not realized. Consequently, Basic Education became one of'a number of alternative educational institutions; one, moreover, suited to the needs of agrarian society. 95 The contradictions embedded in a one-sided acceptance of policy became evident as it was implemented. The philosophical and moral principles of Basic Education were quite broad and general and not unique to Gandhi, but whatever uniqueness and specificity they had was lost in implementation, as emphasis was placed on the moral and philosophical imperatives for individual change in values. Elements which were distinctive and also radical in Gandhi's philosophy of education were toned down. The process of institutionalization of Basic Education under- went familiar phases common to any other educational enterprise and its mass expansion: training of teachers, administration, curriculum, the integration of craft orientation into regular school-type intellectual activities; research into various aspects of Basic Education. These became major concerns of implementatidn. Committees were appointed to examine the functioning of Basic Education, and give their evaluation and recommendations.1 The re-organization and re-orientation of formal, tradi- tional schools along the lines of Basic Schools became a key program 1Zakir Hussain Committee, which brought out a report known as Basic National Education (1939); The Central Advisory Board of Educa- tion appointedia committee of two officers for inspection of Basic Schools in various parts of India, their findings published under the name The Pires-Lakhani Report; Committee on the Productive Aspects of Basic Education appointed an Assessment Committee which gave its findings in The Report of the Assessment Committee on Basic Education (1956). The wEFk ofialT’these committees was to evaluate the progress of Basic Education and offer recommendations. The Zakir Hussain Report provided a detailed syllabus for Basic Schools; Pires-Lakhani Report examined the productive and economic value of Basic Education, and while approving it, provided a guide- line for making it more effective. The Assessment Committee in its report advocated the orientation of all elementary schools to the basic pattern. 96 since the inception of the First Five Year Plan. Since the early 19505 there has been a continuous expansion of Basic Schools. More teacher training institutes have been created. Attempts have been made to incorporate elements of Basic Education into primary schools. But all these efforts have been oriented toward the rural areas, with the result that Basic Education has made few inroads into the urban setting (Avinashlingam, 1964; Zachariah, 1970). Assessment and Outcomes of Basic Education With respect to the quantative aspects of Basic Education, some progress was made, especially in the area of teacher training. From 114 training institutes the number (estimated) was up to 1,424 institutes of Basic Teacher Training in 1965-66. By the end of the Third Plan Period (1965-66) it was hoped to convert all teacher training institutions for elementary education teachers to the Basic pattern (Avinashilingam, 1964; Salamatullah, 1964). The teacher is the pivot of any system of education and the more so in basic education which is a radical departure, both in theory and in practice, from the traditional pattern of schooling (Avinashilingam, 1964:67). There is a recognition, however, that this quantitative growth has to be accompanied by qualitative changes in the training provided. A number of reports and studies have pointed to the shortcomings of training institutions, the facilities, the curriculum content, training techniques, and a host of other related problems have been discussed (Salamatullah, 1964:310). The number of Basic Schools has grown tremendously. Between 1950-51 to 1965-66, the number of schools multiplied five times, 97 although the proportion of increase in Basic Schools has been less than that of elementary schools (Salamatullah, 1964). In 1944, there were 261 Basic Schools, with eight training centers. In 1950-51, the number increased considerably to 33,767 junior and senior Basic Schools (primary and middle schools), with 114 training centers. By 1965-66, the estimate of number of schools went up five times, to 169,700 junior and senior Basic Schools, with a targeted rise in training schools to 1,424 (Avinashilingam, 1964; Salamatullah, 1964). But compared to the existence and expansion of traditional, academic type elementary schools, the enrollments in Basic Schools were not considered to be very encouraging, even though they increased substantially. "The trend in the expansion of basic educa- tion does not warrant the hope that it will, in fact, become the universal system of education at the elementary stage in the near future" (Salamatullah, 1964:310). Qualitative evaluations of Basic Education generally take two forms. They are either an assessment of the internal constraints and shortcomings found in Basic Schools, or they are external, relating to the community's attitudes, opinions, and beliefs concern- ing Basic Schools. Much has been written on the internal weaknesses of Basic Education. These include the training of administrative personnel, production of books, training of teachers, and financial conStraints faced by Basic Schools (Avinashilingam, 1964; Salamatullah, 1964; Koshy, 1968). 98 The idea of Gandhi that Basic Education should be self- supporting through the production and sale of crafts and thus provide a creative education and take the financial burden off the state has not been realized. Consequently, the expenditure on Basic Education continues to increase substantially. With respect to teacher education, in spite of the expansion of teaching schools, a statement of Salamatullah's sums up the picture: A type of sub-standard education is doled out to the prospective teachers of basic schools. Such teachers cannot, therefore, be expected to handle the problems of basic education imaginatively and with a reasonable degree of success, especially when no arrangement worth the name is made for their in-service education (1964:314). Since most elementary and Basic Schools are located in rural areas, a number of problems have been ennumerated by writers on the subject (see Balwabtrai Metha Committee, "Democratic Decentralization,“ in Elementary Education, pp. 452—470). There has been a gradual absorption of some Basic Education into elementary schools, but this has occurred without the latter being transformed into the former. It has been pointed out by many writers that to date elementary education has benefitted from some of the ideas of Basic Education, but their argument is from the side of the theory and practice of education. A number of non-basic schools appear to give regular citizenship training. Many have already introduced one or another aspect of citizenship. Many of them devote at least some time for school cleaning (Avinashilingam, 1964:81 [quote from unpublished report of the study bpramakrishna Mission Vidyalaya Teachers College, Coinbatorel). 99 The influence of Basic Schools on elementary schools often means the introduction of craft-orientation, physical and manual work, activities such as health, social service, and cultural activities (Salamatullah, 1964:324). The Report of the Assessment Committee on Basic Education laid important emphasis on the orientation of elementary education to the basic pattern. In the opinion of the assessors, Basic Education schools were spotty and had not multiplied fast enough; the result being that elementary schools had not been transformed. This had caused Basic Education to appear "artificial." As a result the report recommends the ”replacement of the vertical process of 'con- verting' non-basic schools to the basic pattern by the horizontal process of 'orienting' non-basic schools to the basic pattern" (Avinashilingam, 1964:77). Some suggestions for inclusion in the traditional curriculum were: activity should be natural and pur- posive; should involve learning with doing; and lead to emotional and intellectual growth; involvement must be such that the learner engages in the process and understands and accepts the activity and is able to evaluate the outcomes (Avinashilingam, 1964:78). The teaching of cleanliness, introduction of crafts, social and cultural activities, community self-government, and the involvement of youth in useful community activities were some of the elements of Basic Schools. However, as one writer points out, in order that elementary schools be oriented to the Basic School pattern, and commitment of administrative personnel and teachers to Basic Education as an ideal 100 and achievable goal is necessary. But often, under the guise of "academic standards" the "life-centered curriculum in basic education may be virtually shifted to the subject matter" emphasis of elementary schools (Salamatullah, 1964:325). As the Assessment Report also indicates, ' If basic schools do not generally furnish a better picture, it is largely due to the fact that educational administration still remains unimaginative and unable to keep pace with the fresh demands of a new situation (Avinashilingam, 1964:77). The issue of external constraints on the expansion of Basic Education has to do with community attitudes and perceptions con- cerning Basic Education. An opinion survey conducted by the Sri Ramakrishna Mission Vidyalaya Teachers College, Coimbatore on the causes of resistance to Basic Education found a general belief among the people that academic standards are lower in the basic schools. Another factor which met with resistance from parents was the craft orientation, and the fact that children had difficulty finding admission to high schools. The view that standards are low was held by school adminis- trators as well as parents. The lack of books, the emphasis on activity, the lack of homework and examinations were cited as weaknesses. By and large, people seem to have developed an attitude of apathy, if not hostility, towards basic education. This may be due to the very nature of the social system pre- vailing in the country rather than to any defect inherent in basic education itself. After all, ours is a class- society in which dominant classes by tradition want to keep themselves aloof from all kinds of productive work-- a factor which is regarded as the very life-breath of basic education . . . . And to make matters worse, Government 101 policy regarding recruitment_to positions of prestige and power still puts a premium on the academic content of education (Salamatullah, 1964:315). Another constraint has been the aspirations of the people, as a result of the achievement of political democracy. Formal schooling is viewed as an important means to economic mobility. Consequently, public pressure has been brought to bear in a number of cases to transform Basic Schools into the academic types. The lack of success of Basic Schools may be due to the existence of two types or alternatives available to the people to choose from. The status quo that formal education stands for and encourages has very formidable, strong and deep roots. Gandhi was highly conscious of the strengths of this status quo and while his ideas to undercut it were revolutionary, the institutional settings in which they were formulated were not sufficiently radical-- witness the existence of the status quo! Given the educational options that exist and the perceptions of the future rewards to be obtained--via education, individuals will choose that type of education which maximizes the future attainment of those rewards. If this is described as a status quo by some, by others it is perceived as a realistic appraisal of the situation as it exists. A survey of research studies on Basic Education shows that the output has been meagre. Slightly over twenty studies have been done by individuals, professional organizations and institutions. Masters and doctoral dissertations on the subject of Basic Education number about 90 out of a total of 3,000 dissertations submitted for 102 degrees in education in Indian. institutions. This was computed over a 22 year period from 1939 to 1961 (Koshy, 1968:275). There is in the research an implicit or unquestioned acceptance of the ideals to be achieved through education. The whole scheme [of Basic Education] is based on the belief that education alone can bring social change. Therefore, the educational reconstruction of India was an g_ riori condition for social rejuvenation (Koshy, 1968: 76 . Breaking down the research studies into subject-matter areas, Koshy describes some of the positive and negative findings of the researches into Basic Education. For instance, that it is psychologically sound and that sociological studies show that it leads to the formation of favorable attitudes among children, although there are no comparative studies done in these areas. Other studies show neutral or negative findings. For example, in the area of evaluations and measurements of subject matter learning, comparative findings varying populations of Basic School students and traditional school students vary from positive, to neutral to negative. Small scale surveys of parent- teacher attitudes to Basic Education show favorable views, but again no comparative data is available. The concept of Basic Education has undergone modification over time within the framework of official reports and commissions. The Education Commission Report (1964-66) viewed Basic Education and work experience to be similar. This redefinition was considered to be more in keeping with a society oriented toward industrialization, with consequent demands upon education. There has been a "shift of emphasis in terms of a new science-oriented society“ (Biswas and 103 Agrawal, 1971:285). The term "work-experience" is gradually replacing Basic Education in official use. Another report, Resolution of the National Policy on Education (1968) does not even mention Basic Education, although it views work-experience as integral to education (Biswas and Agrawal, 1971). CHAPTER VI ANALYSIS AND EVALUATION OF THE GANDHIAN PHILOSOPHY OF SOCIAL CHANGE IN ACTION Some General Characteristics offiGandhian Ideology "Gandhi was a man of action, not a social and political theorist" (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:27). Gandhi's perceptions and insights of reality and his ideas concerning social, political, economic conditions were based as much on his personal experiences, as on the confrontation of those experiences with the Indian reality (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971; Joshi, 1970). The philosophy that he evolved, if his ideas can be described as such, were "Experiments With Truth." Joshi describes his quest as a search for a new identity for India "at once non-traditional and non-western" (1970:141). Joshi warns though that it would be difficult to conceive his ideas as a theory or a model of development. They are to be considered more in the nature of "perceptions" rather than "prescriptions" for the problems Indian society faced and faces still. In that respect his insights are just as relevant today (Joshi, 1970:141). Joshi summarily dismisses Gandhi's ideas which were presented in "metaphysical and universalistic terms" as obscurantist and sets out to discuss the relevance of his economic and social ideas (p. 142). 104 105 It is difficult, however, to strip the spiritual and meta- physical elements in a discussion of his secular ideas. There are paradoxically strengths and weaknesses in both which require elucida- tion. Besides, as Gandhi himself put it, ". . . all my activities, whatever their outer form, are fundamentally religious" (Gandhi, 1962:165-66). An attempt in India at social change, which is typically Indian in origin, is "social reconstruction.“ At the highest level of abstraction, it encompasses ideas "for the revitali- zation and transformation of Indian values, norms, and institutions" (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:1). Its historical antecedents date back to early nineteenth century. It has been described variously as the "Hindu Renaissance," "cultural renaissance," and the "Indian renaissance" (Agehananda and Bharti, 1970; Gupta, 1971; Mackenzie Brown, 1959; Ostergaard and Currell, 1971). It is mentioned in connection with the social reform efforts of such well-known leaders as Ram Mohan Roy, Vivekananda, Ranade and Tilak. Most of the social reform efforts, however, were initiated by the urban elite, for the urban classes, and they were expressed and formulated through "legal and institutional changes" (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:1). But, even so, as Gupta argues, "The locus of change was still the individual heart." In the case of Ram Mohan Roy it was "the authority of private judgment." For Devendra Nath Tagore, it was "human reason," and for Keshav Chandra Sen, it was "individual conscience" (Gupta, 1971:73). But social reconstruction was, from its very beginnings, rurally oriented. It found expression in Tagore's project in 106 agricultural change (Elmhurst, 1968); but it was Gandhi who trans- formed it into a national movement--"through the exercise of philosophy of action, satyagraha" (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:2). The historical roots of social reconstruction, according to Gupta, were laid by Vivekananda. It was by Vivekananda and later Gandhi that the "ethical principle for the self-realization of the individual" was converted to a "principle of social ethics . . . (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:30; also Gupta, 1971 and Rudolph and Rudolph, 1967). By separating "religious principles and religious practices," Vivekananda made the first an effective instrument for social change. The evils were in the practices not in the principles of religion. "This was accompanied by a normative upgrading of ultimate goals and immediate behavior patterns, relevant to Hindu metaphysics" (Gupta, 1971:76). This included a reformulation of the man-God relationship. Mgkti;-self—realization--was extroverted in the "worship of God through man" (1971:77). Religion was moved from an other-worldly to a this-worldly orientation. "The subjective pursuit of mgkti_was transformed into an other-directed activity which could predispose personal commitment towards collective goal-attainment" (1971:79). The essentially individualistic, asocial attitudes were to be replaced by "altruistic unselfishness." The notion of caste purity and "ascribed privilege" replaced by "the ideals of equality and universal freedom" (1971:78). Vivekananda modernized Hinduism while "hinduising India's modernity" (1971:79). (This is similar, according 107 to Gupta, to the way in which Calvin, in Weber's thesis, appears to have "christianized modernization in the west," 1971:213.) Gandhi represents a second major normative transformation of traditional ideas and values. According to Gupta, his "reformulation is a logical extension of Vivekanandian breakthrough. Renunciation and service are fused to spiritualize politics and evolve a new model of socio-economic reconstruction" (1971:79).- Both start with a distinctively Indian perception of human nature and social order. To both of them, stability signifies a restoration of transcendent reality, while change occurs in the process of realizing the latent divinity of individuals (1971:79). A general understanding of Gandhi's views of man and society are relevant to the discussion that will follow. Ennumerated below are some of his ideas concerning the nature of both. Nature of Man In the Gandhian philosophy each individual is unique and has a distinct personality, which is not static, but dynamic. Men, irrespective of outward differences, are fundamentally the same and, ultimately, good. The potential for good is inherent in man, consequently men are perfectable. Gandhi had faith in the technique of conversion; he believed in the "possibility of improving man" (Prasad, 1964:207). Gandhi posited an "evolutionary process by which men, as they gained increasing insight into spiritual Truth, would become progressively less violent" (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:30). Individual self- realization is an important element in Gandhi's philosophy. 108 Individual transformation begins as he learns to practice the values of Truth and non—violence. The transformation of society and mankind were to be achieved through "Constructive work and Nonviolent Non-cooperation" (Bose, 1967:410). The former was to be a new mode of production, in which all men would be toilers, and wealth would be distributed equitably if not equally. Nonviolent non-cooperation meant not the ouster of ‘ the present rulers by use of force, .I!‘ ' ‘ lLZim‘" lg... . . . but to convert them by determined, yet civilized refusal to subscribe to proved wrongs. The aim of conver- sion is to secure their cooperation in helping their erst- while victims in building up a new social and economic order based on justice, equality and freedom (Bose, 1967: 410-11). Social change is to occur "not through punishment but by conver- sion . . ." (1967:411). Gandhi, like many well-known thinkers and leaders in India "cared more for man's inner environment than his outer . . ." (Rudolphs, 1967:160). The ideal individual is one who is free from constraints '” and coercion from above and without, mindful of the rights and welfare of others, one who identifies with the community, is governed by internal and external discipline, practices an altruistic and public ethic, lives in harmony with the group, provides disinterested service to the community, displays a cooperative spirit, and is not competitive. The terminology Gandhi uses for defining problems, both at the individual and social levels, is drawn from Hindu Sanskritic texts and Hindu cosmology. He undertakes, as several writers point out, a "normative upgrading" of the traditional ethic, utilizing 109 concepts of satyagraha, ahimsa, makti, and dharma (truth in action, non-violence, self-realization, and duty). Gandhi completely turned around the "unsystematic theory of British imperialism" by which they stereotyped Hindu character and personality. By drawing upon traditional cultural concepts . .he revived the traditional view of courage, a view that carried with it commitments to non- -violence, self- suffering, and self-restraint, qualities Englishmen had perceived differently and identified as cowardice. The path to courage that Gandhi showed his countrymen had fallen into disrepute among those affected by British p. power and ideas. He now gave it new life and meaning by making clear the exacting discipline it required in action and the kind of sacrifice and self-control it involved (Rudolph and Rudolph, 1967:248). But, as Gupta points out, the institutional correlates of the reform efforts have not been worked out. "The supreme ethical achievement does not denote a new world order, but merely a new world view" (1971:86). All reform efforts are directed at individual transfbrma- tion. A homology between desired norms and individual action is assumed and the institutionalization of norms and action goes apace with the upgrading of the religious norms of good conduct. Reality however shows otherwise: "The prophet is deified, and in this process an imaginary distance is created between his supra-human virtues and one's own human shortcomings" (1971:87). It is only through isolated and committed individuals that change is initiated, not through institutional transformation. Joshi goes so far as to say that "Even the slogan of the socialist pattern of society seeks to induce change in the hearts of the individuals . . . . The 110 modernization of India presupposes extra and intense initiative on the part of selected individuals" (1971:90-91). Nature of Society "Society cannot be good unless individual men are good" (Prasad, 1964:98). A good society is possible when there is coopera- tion, self-discipline, and a sense of responsibility. Self- government, self-management, mutual cooperation and sharing, equality, freedom and brotherhood, are necessary ingredients if men are to create a viable society. Ours is a movement of self-purification . . . . If Swaraj was not meant to civilize us and to purify and stabilize our civilization, it would be nothing worth. The very essence of our civilization is that we give a paramount place to morality in all our affairs, public and private (Gandhi, 1962:184). Gandhi advocated a partyless, decentralized democracy. Society is not viewed in terms of classes, although concern is with the masses of underprivileged and poor. Gandhi was aware of the exploitation of the masses. He knew that society was divided "into those who toiled, and the rest who lived on the toils of others" (Bose, 1967:234). But social change, he envisaged "through construc- tive work and satyagraha" (1967:241). Because of his commitment to the principle of non-violence, he did not advocate the overthrow of government or the state authority. His was a gradualist approach toward a stateless society. He advocated not confrontation and conflict, but consensual politics. Social change was to be both "efficient and economical," without at the same time leading to "concentration of power" (1967:305). III Gandhi drew an analogy of satyagraha with war. Just as war requires a period of preparation, so too does satyagraha require an intense period of preparation which is non-violent. This is described as constructive work. The central object of constructive work is to build up a democratic and equalitarian social and economic order by decentralization of the production of the vital necessities of life. The means of production of those needs are ultimately to vest in public bodies and not in private hands. Gandhi held that when man's responsibilities are related to the needs of a small manageable area, they function much better than when very large organizations are run from a distance through personally little known representatives (Bose, 1967:306). Swaraj, self government, meant more than political independence-- it means a society committed to the welfare of all. Swaraj is defined as ". . . freedom of the masses from all forms of exploita- tion or inequality, achieved through the promotion and organization of their non-violent strength" (Bose, 1967:197). The ideal society is one in which there is no need for government. Gandhi envisioned a stateless society, fully decentral- ized, constituting organic and democratic communities. It would be based on values of equality, brotherhood, freedom, organized on the idea of power of the people. Self-government would be through self- discipline, and all would participate in their own governance. The concern is not so much with programs of development, but self- government. But, for the politically motivated who sought independence Vivekananda and Gandhi--and their metaphysics--symbolized a radical change, not only in the area of social transformation, but for the 112 ouster of the British as well. Vivekananda was “hailed as a socialist by a devoted band of revolutionaries" (Gupta, 1971:78). And Gandhi's program of constructive non-violence, which aimed at building up mass support, also "provided a training ground for independence fighters" (Ostergaard and Currell, l971:3). Although both were committed to the raising of the welfare of all, neither of them desired political confrontation (Gupta, 1971; Ostergaard and Currell, 1971). Gandhi, however, conceived the weapons of freedom and liberation to be spiritual ones. The backgrounds and sources of all activities were to be spiritual ones. "Hence the necessity for the strictest purity of conduct and character" (Gandhi, 1962:197). His advice to the workers was that this was not a difficult task, nor an impossible one. That it had not been attained did not mean that it should not be tried. "Do not fight shy of the experiment. The experiment will itself provide the momentum for more and more effort" (Gandhi, 1962: 197). Truth and non-violence were not only to be a principle and creed but they should become "part and parcel" of one's being. Gandhi, both in his public and private life, attempted to negate the dualism of "inner progress" and "the service of society." The distinction, according to him, was "due to an error of thought." I believe, and it is also my experience, that all that is against the progress of the soul is also against the true interest of society in general. The progress of the soul can best be achieved, according to me, through the service of society . . . (Gandhi, 1962:242). The evolution of Gandhian ideas concerning individual and society, as they found expression in the Sarvodaya Movement spear- headed by Vinobha Bhave and J. P. Narayan, are similarly committed 113 to the ideals of Truth and Non-violence. No attempt is made, accord- ing to Joshi, to "challenge the Establishment and the economic and political status quo” (Joshi, 1970:150). In the Sarvodaya philosophy: "There is thus to be no direct frontal attack on the state, but a progression from free central government through the decentralized self-governing state to the condition of pure anarchy"(Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:41). This utopian condition is far from being realized, and Joshi goes so far as to state that "post independence Gandhism has been denuded of its commitment to radical social change, and therefore, of its revolutionary potential“ (1970:150). The ideal society is to be established by transforming ”individual character." This was the philosophy of Gandhi, and later Vinobha Bhave and J. P. Narayan, who eschew "the pursuit of power in their efforts to change society by changing men" (Rudolph, 1961:391). Gandhi's political philosophy was essentially individual, radiated through mind and action and not at all through an ideological programme, still less through a political party or political institutions. Hence, it is peculiarly vulnerable to the passing of time. Gandhi attempted to work through his immediate disciples, and through the Indian masses as his followers, with virtually no fixed organiza- tion and with something like indifference to the normal end of politics, that is, power (Tinker, 1964:262-63; see also Rudolph, 1961). Following Gandhi, both Vinobha Bhave and Jayaprakash Narayan portray similar ideals. and are attempting to bring about change outside the political processes. For them, as for Gandhi, social change--the betterment of human and social life--is essentially a moral problem (Prasad, 1966). 114 Some Outcomes and Results of the Gandhian Ideas in Practice The reconstruction of Indian society that Gandhi envisioned was rural and mass oriented. In attempting to mobilize the peasants in India, Gandhi advocated a "populist ideology" . . . put forward a doctrine of 'trusteeship', advocating class peace, and designating the landlords as 'trustees' for the exploited peasant! When Gandhi led peasant 'struggles', they were those that were not directed against the landlords but against the British Raj . . . nevertheless, that involvement with the peasantry was one which infused many of the Congress leaders and cadres with a populist ideology . . . (Alavi, 1975:1237). In fact, in what is now regarded as his "last will and testament" Gandhi stated that if India is to develop, the first step that must be taken is for the present Congress Party to disband itself and create a totally new cadre devoted to development work. This cadre would be known as the Lok Sevak Sangh--"an apolitical people's service association" (Rudolph, 1961:385). The introduction of land reform legislation, coupled with Community Development, and later Panchayati Raj, the National Extension Service, and Basic Education to improve rural social life, agriculture and rural based industry were initially founded on certain Gandhian ideals. These development efforts were based on the notion that "the 'felt needs' of the people and the demands of the national economy were coincident (Hanson, 1966:407). As Hanson explains it, the tendency in policy, especially from the time of Gandhi, has been to assume that somehow the multitude of divisive forces in Indian society can be overcome or eliminated and consensus and cooperation achieved. There is a "Rousseauan” hope that 115 consensus can be achieved by the discovery of "a unique general will which must then become the 'real self' of every individual partici- pant" (Hanson, 1966:259; see also Rudolph, 1961). Conflict, interest-adjustment, and limited consensus were some of the characteristics of democratic institutions that were looked down upon (1966:259). The concept of selfless and non- political community service, which Gandhi formulated has been a [3 dominant motive in Indian society and politics (see Tinker, 1964; Rudolph, 1961; Hanson, 1966:260). Carried to an extreme and combined with a Gandhi- inspired enthusiasm for social service, this attitude can lead to complete withdrawal from ordinary political life and to the devotion of a great man's intellectual talents to the formulation of utopian proposals for the 'recon- struction of the Indian polity', such as those advanced by Jayaprakash Narayan, who appears to think that the faction- ridden village can provide the foundation of a pyramidal democracy without parties, in which decisions are taken by unanimous consent (Hanson, 1966:261). Indian village society has been romanticized as a harmonious and homogenous community by Indian social reformers. The reality of social, political, and economic stratifications are overlooked. There is an assumption that unanimity of interests pervades village life (Hanson, 1966; Rudolph, 1961). In the implementation of development programs two types of orientations become evident. One, already alluded to, is the vision of harmonious Indian village society. Jayaprakash Narayan, for instance, looks to the past to find the "lost soul" of an "ancient country." He asks for a revival of the concept of dharma, not by a legislative act but in an organic manner. "Dharma must arise from 116 life itself--1ife that is vital enough, real enough, organic enough to be able to throw up codes and laws for its internal regulation“ (Prasad, 1964:207). W. H. Morris-Jones, in a cogent critique of Narayan's reconstituted polity based on the ideas of ancient communities, says that the latter are uncertain, ordinary and remote. Uncertain in time and place, ordinary in that they were not peculiar to India, and remote because, while some aspects may be found even today, "it is in its fullness another world" (Morris-Jones, 1960). The appeal for the transformation of Indian society is directed at the individual "by disciplining of the bodily appetites . . by sharing together the good things, by keeping wants under control . . ." (Prasad, 1964:156). On a societal level, decentrali- zation and de-institutionalization cannot be legislated into being, according to Narayan. Reform "always implies a total removal of institutional restraints. The prophet always blames the system . . . but reforms the individual" (Gupta, 1971:86). The other orientation in planned social change, found especially among program planners and implementers, is to pay "lip service . . . to the concept of planning according to felt needs . . ." (Dube, 1958:150). Urban intellectuals and professionals consider the village to be backward and conservative, a place where higher castes and classes dominate lower and new ideas and technology advance at a snail's pace, the place least rather than most likely to provide the inspiration and the means for tomorrow's utopia (Rudolph, 1967:217). An important function or role assigned to education by those who consider it an important element in social change is to change 117 these very perceptions of people concerning both means and ends which they must seek. But education, of whatever type of character or uniqueness, cannot function in iSolation from the ongoing network of perceptions and values and desires. The "vocabularies of motive that prevail in a society" are socially patterned (Mills, 1959:162). And it is a form of idealism to hope that individual attitudes, motives and values can be transformed simply by providing a specific 11 type of education, while other institutions of society are allowed to function unchecked. Cultural and economic and material concerns are woven into people's perceptions of benefits and rewards and gains from educa- tion or any development effort that require change on their part. Social scientists who adopt a psychological and individualistic point of view would state that it is precisely these misguided per- ceptions on the part of individuals that need to be changed. People's perceptions, their cognition and motivation, and also values, success, self-interest and rewards are assumed to be psychological states (Homans, 1964:816-17). While these elements are integral to a definition of a situation or problem they are weak as explanations, for example, in the proposition that Basic Educa- tion failed because people did not adopt it. This is an insufficient and incomplete explanation. Psychological properties explain behaviors of individuals, but they cannot explain the conditions operating in society which contributed to the failure of Basic Education. For example, Gandhi's major concern was with revitalizing village economy and harnessing education toward this attempt. On the 118 other hand, government plans and policy were oriented toward rapid economic and industrial growth. Not only were the goals divergent and incompatible, so were the educational means. Given a variety of educational institutions, individuals can be expected to choose those which they perceive to be most responsive to their own needs, inclinations, and desires. Appeals to individuals to choose one over the other were made on moral grounds requiring persuasion and . .‘ 9y 4. conversion. It may work with some individuals, but to expect all iifir. m9 ' individuals to respond alike is to assume an unlikely uniformity of -‘ behavior. There is no assumption here that social conditions or institutions or norms exert coercive power over individuals, that they force individuals to act one way or the other, or that indi- viduals are merely puppets governed by the system. Norms, defined by Wilhelm as "social conditions," and "means" . . . are standards jgp_social conduct; they are guides that direct the expression of social behavior. As such, norms are not equivalent to conduct; norms are constructs for analyzing social action rather than facets of social behavior (Wilhelm, 1967:24). To further clarify the Gandhian attempt at individual and social transformation, I shall draw upon Ostergaard and Currell's classification of "norm-oriented" and "value-oriented" movements. On a conceptual level, the former expresses "certain regulatory principles" identified as necessary for action. The movement then attempts ‘ to restore, protect, modify, or create norms in the name of a generalized (norm-oriented belief. People subscribing to such beliefs may demand a law or a regulatory agency to 119 control behavior. Political pressure groups of all kinds are typical norm-oriented movements (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:21). Values are more generalized and diffused than norms. "They state in general terms the desirable ends which serve as a guide to human endeavour." A value-oriented movement is "a collective attempt to restore, protect, modify, or create values in the name of a generalized (value-oriented) beliéf." Values call for a total reconstruction of self and society; and are concerned with the moral basis of life. Its adherents envisage a new world and not merely an improvement of individuals or a reform of institutions, even though the latter are aspects of regeneration. Such beliefs contain a vision of future harmony and stability which is in direct contrast with the decay and instability of the present (1971:21). Examples of value-oriented movements, according to the authors are "messianic religious movements," and "utopian socialist movements" (1971:21). Movements that aim at changing institutions usually focus on gaining power over the institutions of society. Those which focus on changing individuals tend "to emphasize the satisfactions to be derived from participation" (1971:20). Although Gandhi saw the necessity of changing both, the belief was that individual change would "inevitably produce institutional change" (1971:20; see also Gupta, 1971). The ideas of Gandhi as they became institutionalized in Basic Education did not lead to transformation of the existing institutions of education, nor did they lead to a change in the environment, or the re-structuring of other institutions through which individuals 120 were to find fulfillment. Persuasion and conversion of individuals to a particular value system through education was enshrined in the system of education. Consequently, a particular ideology of what was desirable for the masses was propagated (Freire, 1972:83). A common pattern of shortcomings and weaknesses found in Basic Education are evident also in the implementation of other types of development programs, such as Community Development.) Panchayati Raj, and Extension Services. Most reasons that are advanced for the lack of expansion and popularity of Basic Education pertain to its internal workings--lack of proper teacher education, problems of introducing handicrafts into the school curriculum, lack of administrative know-how, inadequate resources and facilities, costs of financing, and inadequate research-~or to the fact that there were weaknesses in the relationship between Basic Schools and other levels of education. There are, however, some external explanations that need to be considered in order to put the failure of Basic Education in a proper perspective. Integral to Basic Education was the concept of manual labour. Gandhi hoped to use education as a means for transforming other institutions. He hoped to transform people's attitudes toward work. by dignifying labour by integrating it with intellectual pursuits. In the process he envisioned an economic and social transformation. Gandhi was not unaware that caste hierarchy assigns low status to manual labour. He hoped to change that by personal example. He took up spinning and leather work, and within Basic Education itself handicrafts became a symbol of manual labour. 121 But Basic Education was rejected by both high and low status groups--by the former because it was considered demeaning and because for cultural and economic reasons the local village elite can hardly be expected to usher in a classless, and casteless society. The poor and the lower castes opposed Basic Education because they looked upon it as an attempt to prevent their children from acquiring a “lottery ticket" for rising on the social and economic ladder (Zachariah, 1970:99). They viewed Basic Education as an attempt to maintain them in their low economic and social status. Another impediment to the success of Basic Education resided in the fact that almost all Basic Schools were established in rural areas. Moreover, the modernizing elite responsible for implementing Basic Education were themselves Western-oriented in their education and in their world view. while the local elites were interested in maintaining the status quo (Zachariah, 1970). After Gandhi, a dedicated band of followers committed to the aims of Basic Education took over the cause, but they lacked the appeal that Gandhi's charismatic leadership provided to mobilize the masses. As Zachariah points out, "Gandhi had unfortunately made no attempt to institutionalize this contact" (1970:103; see also Gupta, 1971); ". . . the inability of the government to mobilize the ordinary people is perhaps the crucial reason for the failure of efforts such as basic education .. ." (1970:104-05). But, in order to do that, the government would have "to bypass the established elite at the state and local level to organize the ordinary villages" (1970:104). To do so would require revolutionary action. 122 The modernizing elite which is represented at the federal level, be it remembered, also come from the upper strata of Indian society. Although it differs from the established elite in that it desires social and economic development, it wants such development in an evolutionary and not in a revolutionary fashion (Zachariah, 1970:104). Policy concerning rural development is not only made by the towns but it is also to some extent made for the towns. This is further aggravated by alliances between urban elites and big farmers, the benefits flowing from the one to the other (Lipton, 1968:141). A number of social scientists have also examined rural development strategy over the same time period, that is, the first two decades of development since Indian Independence. They have documented the impact of Community Development, Panchayati Raj, National Extension Service, and other inputs into rural development; and the effects of these on the rural masses in terms of solving problems of poverty, unemployment and rural-urban dichotomies. An authoritative treatise on "Poverty in India: Policies and Programmes" published in 1971, has attempted to quantify poverty in India. The findings are that 42 per cent of the population of India is so poor that they cannot afford a daily minimum Caloric intake. And this after two decades of development (Dandekar and Rath, 1971). Innumerable case studies are available which document that the peasant landed elite is the group that has done well as a result of government assistance to rural areas. They are the main beneficiaries of the new system of democratic decentralization known as panchayati raj . . . they have absorbed the lion's share othhe'beneths accruing to the countryside from the Community Projects and National 123 Extension Services . . . . Their power derives from the inability of the administration to do anything effective in the countryside without their cooperation and from the fact that they possess an electoral influence which can make and unmake governments, particularly at the state level (Hanson, 1966:241). Like the businessmen, they play an ambiguous role in the process of economic development. In so far as they are content to establish themselves as local elites, they con- tribute to the ossification of rural society, thereby restricting the initiatives and throttling the responses of others (Hanson, 1966:242). Paradoxically, the "business class" in urban areas, and the "kulak class" from the rural areas are the main beneficiaries of socialism. The former has benefitted from the opening up of new markets, and the limitations on competition, and the latter from the introduction of new seeds, water, fertilizer, credit, and other related services. Can we conclude from the lack of success of various programs and practices of development that were imbued with Gandhian ideals that the ideals were inconsequential, that they embody an inadequate understanding and comprehension of Indian reality, or that the extent to which events have veered away from Gandhian vision of the future of Indian society indicates how outdated his ideas are today? According to some writers, Gandhian ideals have found expression in Indian foreign policy in and through the philosophy of non-alignment, and non—violence itself, as a political weapon, has gained popularity in the West (Tinker, 1964; Rudolph, 1967). Those ideals, as embodied in the Sarvodaya Movement carried on by Vinobha Bhave and Jayaprakash Narayan, constitute "the repository of the Indian conscience" (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:15). 124 To document from just one study concerning the influence of Cahdhism: Harijans have been attempting to break away from age-old social, cultural and economic disabilities. Although they are facilitated in this by new laws and legislations, they nonetheless come into conflict with the dominant castes. Over more than two decades of independence they have become sufficiently politicized and organized to make their demands felt: . . . the Harijans have forged rapidly ahead in their bid for civic equality. But this journey has been by no means smooth or easy; the price of every significant advance has been a measure of violence . . . today they are no longer in a mood to have their houses burnt or their property destroyed without retaliation (Beteille, 1969:186). Does the fact that the Harijans are seeking self-determination, whether the rest of society is willing to grant it to them or not, reflect well or forbode ill for the future of Gandhism? The answer depends upon which particular elements of Gandhian ideology one professes. Swamy provides three reasons why the ideas of decentraliza- tion, labour intensive rural works and village self-sufficiency receded into the background in development planning. (1) The Congress Party after independence, was transformed into a political electoral machine. Gandhi foresaw this and called for the transformation of the political machinery into a totally new cadre devoted to develop- ment projects. But the political system as it now exists is not accountable to any one. (2) The bureaucratic system was simply a "law and order" maintenance body. (3) The educational system inherited from the British was geared to producing clerks and white- collar workers. Neither the educational system nor the bureaucracy 125 were suited to development work. And each moved away from the principles and ideas of Gandhi. The first casualty, according to Swamy, was the "Swadeshi principle"--the principle of self-reliance that Gandhi advocated (Swamy, 1976). Secular Aspects of Gandhian Ideas and the Social and’Economic Realities The relevance of Gandhi's ideas can be grasped only by demythologizing the religious and metaphysical elements of his thought. Gandhian "transcendental morality and appeal to traditional ideas," are meaningless to the post-independence generations. But what is still relevant are ". . . those aspects of Gandhi's leader- ship that relate to middle-level norms of conduct and to instru- mental rather than ideological effectiveness" (Rudolph, 1967:219). In discussions of the indigeneous nature of some of Gandhian ideas often it is those elements which are least relevant that are emphasized. These can be summed up in the common phrase "the West is materialistic, the East is spiritual" (Bharati, 1968). But it is simplistic to say that Gandhi was against Western ideals and values. His reaction was to some forms of Westernism. The ideas involved in the concept are themselves complex and easily misunderstood. Three distinct elements can be identified within the concept of Westernism: (1) Ideas and values of Westernism mean values of commitment to work, to equality, to humanism, methodical regulation of life as reflected in punctuality, discipline and awareness of obligations to total society; (2) Westernism also means the specific institutions of private enterprise which are organized around the principle of profit 126 making; and ideas embodied in individualism, both of which are found in a particular Western model of economic and social development; and (3) Westernism also means the attitudes, value-preferences, orientation, and way of life of the Westernized elite in one's own society, and these groups may not possess any of the characteristics of modernizing elites in the West (Joshi, 1970:140). It was the first type of Westernism which Gandhi professed E” and practiced. His contributions in the areas of political moderni- ,_ i- zation are significant; his ideas bearing upon "the conduct of politics, a work ethic and economizing behavior with respect to time and resources, and making India's political structures more rational, democratic, and professional," in essence his 'this-worldly asceticism' constitute his greatest contribution (Rudolph, 1967:219). Some ideas from the West he considered totally alien to the Indian way of life-~the ideas of individualism and profit, specifically capital value as a measure of success in any enterprise. Gandhi's objection was to "the allocation of all productive resources on the basis of capital values" (Rivett, 1959:4). The success 0f any enterprise according to him is to be adduced only by the extent to which it satisfied personal needs and the demands of institutions (Rivett, 1959). Gandhi assessed the value of change by its observable impact on the countryside. His essential protest was directed, not against industrialism as such, but against the social disruption that may accompany it (Rivett, 1959:4). He was against the over-emphasis on the use of Western models of deve10pment. The very identification of these as debatable issues 127 is of enormous significance, according to Joshi (1970:146). They remain extremely meaningful and relevant even in the contemporary context (see Schumacher, 1975; Illich, 1973). The conditions of poverty, unemployment, and rural-urban dichotomies were central to his social and economic analysis, and his perceptions and insights reveal that he was a rebel not only against Westernism _ 'l J but also traditionalism. Gandhi's was the only realistic appraisal of the Indian situation and problems. :— 11. His basic merit lay in the fact that he questioned the relevance of the Western model of development to Indian conditions from a non-traditionalist standpoint. . . . This simultaneous criticism of Westernism as well as traditionalism enabled Gandhi to view the problem of Indian development neither as a process of return to the past (i.e., preservation of traditional identity) nor as a process of implantation of Western institutions and values (i.e., Westernization) but as a process of organic evolution and growth (Joshi, 1970:141). But the idiom in which Gandhi spoke was traditional rather than scientific. In this sense his quest for an indigenous model, according to Joshi, represents a beginning and cannot be viewed as a perfected model. "It would be futile, therefore, to look for a mature model of development in Gandhi's ideas" (141). But the basic ingredients are all there: his perceptions of problems facing Indian society are of enduring value, although his prescriptions for solutions to these problems may not be. But in spite of these limita- tions the core of his thought is just as relevant today, and perhaps more so, as the second generation problems of development arise. Gandhi did not hold to an anti-industrialization position as is commonly believed, but he was for minimum-industrialization. As 128 he is said to have reiterated more than once to clear this misunder- standing: "What I am against is large-scale production of things villages can produce without difficulty" (Joshi, 1970:145). Accord- ing to Joshi, the minimum-industrialization views of Gandhi expressed one of the first doubts and questioning "of a universal model of economic and social develOpment valid for all countries and all times" (Joshi, 1970:146). *3 Gandhi's perceptions of rural-urban imbalances, the large number of small landowners, tenants, and landless peasants, and the tradition of handicrafts, and the implications of all these limiting factors for the type of planning for development that should be undertaken remain significant. Moreover, Gandhi was not unaware that the solutions to these problems required changes in property and power structure, attitudes, beliefs, and social organization coupled with institution-building on a vast scale. He was also not oblivious of the tremendous resistance from the vested interests to the implementation of this program. His emphasis on arousing among the toiling masses the consciousness of their own "power“ was a recogni- tion of the basic truth that the task of reconstruction was inseparable from the factor of "power" (Joshi, 1970:149-150). The secular aspects of Gandhi's ideas were overshadowed and "obscured by other ingredients of his thought which had a secondary significance. They did not become the basis of any operational model of Indian development" (Joshi, 1970:150). Gandhi's perceptive analysis of the social, political, and economic realities were over- laid by his religious and ideological doctrines. It is his meta- physical, religious, and spiritual ideas which are kept alive. 129 Today, some of the ideological, religious, and psychological elements of Gandhi's thought have been further idealized and eulogized by some social scientists and educationists and in the social and political contexts his ideas have been ritualized and have undergone a "process of vulgarization" (Joshi, 1970:150). While Gandhi's views and vision of a mass-oriented development, that is "the uncompromising commitment to the interests of the vast masses of small producers," have been taken over by the Sarvodaya workers: Sarvodaya, the Welfare of All, a casteless, classless, stateless, free society of equals being the ultimate social objective, the grand strategy to achieve it is revaluation of values on the part of individuals and groups, leading to progressive changes in social structure and social institu- tions (Ostergaard and Currell, 1971:227). However, as Hoshi points out, "none of the existing interpretations of Gandhian thought and practice seem to challenge the Establishment and the economic and political status quo" (1970:150). If there is an awakening on the part of the masses, Joshi speculates that it will most likely "proceed in opposition to all status qua-oriented or 'gradualist' ideologies including the ossified Gandhism of the post-independence era" (1970:150-51). Whether its realization will follow a path "in conformity with Gandhi's value commitments," that is, his two fundamental precepts of Truth and Non-violence, remains to be seen. If, however, the awakening of the masses . . transcends the bounds of Gandhi's value commitments, it will only conform his prophesy regarding the price that may have to be paid by the privileged classes if they con- tinued to disregard the interests and as irations of the village-dwelling masses (Joshi, 1970:152 . CHAPTER VII SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS The major purpose in presenting the two case studies was to discuss them within the framework of the individualistic psycho- logical approaches in social science. The description of the two case studies, the presuppositions of its mentors, and the analysis of both cases provide sufficient evidence to show that at a level of abstraction and generalization both provide explanations of social change which may be subsumed under individualistic psychological approaches. It must be reiterated, however, that there are a number of points of divergence between McClelland and Gandhi, in spite of certain similarities in presuppositions. In order to avoid any invidious comparison between the two a brief recounting of the similarities and differences at the level of explanation will be provided. Two education programs from India were examined. One was Western in its orientation and assumptions concerning social change, and the other was indigeneous in the type of social change envisioned, and the solutions sought. One program of psychological education was undertaken by David C. McClelland to motivate economic achievement in individuals. The other is the Scheme of Basic Education devised by Gandhi to transform individuals and reconstruct Indian society. 130 131 The issue of major concern to McClelland was economic growth and modernization and ways by which those precesses might be acceler- ated. In searching for the causes of both modernization and economic growth he argued that psychologists have provided the answer, sum- marized by the notion of "need for achievement." Within the hierarchy of motives, the motive to achieve is identified as the most important one in economic growth and development. Through the ~" right type of education, need for achievement could be moved higher up in a person's hierarchy of needs, then exploited as the basis for productive activity. The notion of "need for achievement" leads to focus on the personality of the individual. The barriers to growth and moderniza- tion are seen to be internal to the individual. By the proviSion of a specific type of educational input, a re-orientation in the responses of individuals can be obtained. McClelland selected a group of Indian businessmen for study. The rationale for the selection assumed that individuals from the middle classes have moderately high levels of need for achievement; they are likely to benefit most from the training and, in turn, contribute most to economic growth. Some of the findings of McClelland and his colleagues who undertook to provide psychological training to a group of business- men were the following: 1. The cultural and religious attitudes and beliefs of individuals do not hinder business and entrepreneurial activities. Moreover, those who showed increased business activity after the !: ‘- . -. ii ‘ s’ - airvgvt m—;"(o“ql‘n I32 training were no different from those who did not in the areas of "Subordination, Dependence, Caste rules, Religious behavior, and Feminism" (McClelland, 1969:262). 2. An important finding of the authors was that the effectiveness of g_Achievement training is determined by the participant's situation. "A man cannot convert increased motivation into increased activity unless he has a real opportunity to do so" (McClelland, 1969:311). 3. In examining factors internal to the individual which retard economic growth the attempt was made to tap the "deeper and more subtle" differences between the Changers and Hon-Changers (1969:268). The difference is defined as involving a "style of describing" goals and actions, and a sense of "efficacy" as opposed to "contemplation of a goal state" and "vague global fantasies" (1969:271-72). 4. Another conclusion from the in-depth analysis of four case studies was that "the training courses did not achieve their effectiveness by deep seated transformation of the motivation of participants. Rather, it appears the courses affected individuals by accenting, building upon, or focusing potential for entre- preneurial activity which was already there (1969:305). 5. The difference between the Changers and Non-Changers after the courses, was due to the fact that the former controlled and ran their own businesses and had the scope and independence to carry out new ideas and plans (1969:272). 133 Some general conclusions that become apparent from McClelland's study of motivating economic achievement in individuals are stated below: 1. Although the motive to achieve is a universal human characteristic, according to McClelland, not all individuals express it. Some are more achievement-oriented than others. How is the initial threshold to be determined? By administering a series of tests a person's perception of success or failure at a task, and the tendency to approach or avoid it can be determined (1969:16-17). But, why is there a variation in the performance of the task? More than an individual's high value of success and fear of failure are involved. Besides, are these spontaneous, full-blown attributes of individual personality? McClelland's concern is to search for the causes of economic development--and g_Achievement is discussed as an important variable in this. He is not concerned with how p_ Achievement itself is caused, but only with boosting it by providing training in psychological education. _ 2. The danger in searching for antecedents is narrowing the search to socialization child-rearing practices, or in positing motivational differences as the result of the "status mobility systems" of various groups (LeVine, 1966), or as due to authoritarian structures, and religious ideologies (McClelland, 1961). Inherent in this approach is the problem of reification of ideal-types, as well as that of the "chicken-and-egg," in which the antecedent and consequent pursue each other in a small circle . . ." (Aberle, 1961: 382). I34 3. McClelland views p_Achievement to be directed only to one specific end--economic development. He does not conceive of any other goal of a non-economic nature which individuals may desire to achieve, or that the desire may itself require community support. Achievement is uni-directional, and highly individualistic, the goal is economic growth. Nor does he consider that economic and entre- preneurial activity may co-vary and be complicated by a number of other factors, such as the state of the economy, labor laws, trade union activities, in short the "entrepreneurial environment." 4. The businessmen who were provided the training inputs controlled most of the institutions of any importance in the town. They were selected because they belong to the middleclass and are presumed to have a threshold of motivation to succeed. The fact that they were also provided with other inputs, involving exposure and familiarity with prestigious and influential individuals who have the power to grant trade licenses, for example, is not acknowledged. 5. It seems, finally, that McClelland's attempt to accelerate economic development by the use of a special psychological training program, was limited to those individuals who combine in themselves all the necessary and sufficient criteria for improvement-- both internal and external. _This circular arrangement caters to the chosen few who received the training in order to convert their potential into productive economic activity. The issues that concerned Gandhi entailed a total reconstruc- tion of Indian society. He was concerned with economic, social and 135 cultural hinderances to social change--problems of unemployment, rural-urban dichotomies, the over-emphasis on mechanization and ,industrialization--and on the cultural plane, he was concerned with the problem of untouchability and with a normative upgrading of religious principles by providing religion with a this-worldly orientation. “ Social good is to be guaranteed by the transfbrmation of values, desires, and motives. Through a process of self-purifica- tion, renunciation, and service, men's hearts can be changed. Gandhi considered "inner progress" and the "service of society" as analogous. On a secular plane both of these goals were to be guaranteed by the integration of the concepts of work and education. Both were integral aspects of his educational philosophy. Educa- tion was to be woven around a craft. This would help revitalize village industries and village economy, create mass employment, and in the process, break down cultural barriers, revitalizing the villages morally and economically. Goals that were to be achieved through Basic Education included the following: 1. At the individual level education was to transform the body, mind, and spirit of the child by applying all three to the learning and doing needed in craft-work. This would create economic self-sufficiency for education, while providing jobs for the unem- ployed. In implementation, Gandhi's ideas concerning personality development and child-centered, activity-oriented education relevant to the needs and interests of the child were accepted, 136 while his ideas concerning economic self-sufficiency through the introduction of craft work in schools were modified.1 The value of Gandhian education for the development of personality and character of the individual were acceptable to educationists, but the conse- quences of work and productive activity within the school and its economic and social implications were viewed as adulterating the goals of education. Consequently, the concepts of work and produc- tive activity which Gandhi sought to integrate with intellectual activity were merely ritualized, especially in the symbol of the spinning wheel. 2. On the societal level, the aims of education were to be service and social uplift of the community. The teachers were to communicate a "spirit of sacrifice," faith, and commitment to the students. The introduction of productive work would break down barriers between traditional occupational groups and create dignity and respectability for manual labor. While these ideas of Gandhi were accepted in principle and also implemented, a number of contra- dictions became evident. The Basic School was one of a number of alternative institutions--one, moreover, suited to the needs of the rural masses. Although Basic Education had its own group of com- mitted individuals, bound by a common ideology, supplied by separate government finances and resources and concerned with expanding the institutions of Basic Schools and teacher training institutes, they had a formidable competitor in the traditional formal schools. Both in principle and in practice, elements of Basic Education were contra- dictory to the dominant trends of most government private schools. 137 Each alternative held out promises and potential of different rewards for the individual seeking to fulfill needs and desires from educa- tion. 3. A combination of economic necessity and moral reforma- tion underlay Gandhi's ideas concerning education. Education should pay for itself, while providing and developing the productive and social capacities of individuals. Knowledge would be useful and functional. Through learning craftwork, students would acquire both technical skills of production and intellectual growth through mastering the scientific processes of production. The debate in the implementation of Basic Education was in essence over goals. The issue concerned the desirability and value of education for the individual and society. The type of education Gandhi envisioned, however, did not separate its value for the individual from its value to society. Individual transformation and social change were to occur simultaneously by individual commitment and dedication to specific goals. Discussion While on an intellectual level a debate concerning the pros and cons of Basic Education continues to this day, the implementation of Basic Education made evident the limits of mass societal trans- formation through education. Furthermore, some ambiguities in the relationship between individual change and social change through education became obvious. On the one hand were the goals of societal transformation to be achieved through Basic Education and on the other were the needs, desired, and inclinations of all people. For 138 the program to be a success it required a commonality of interest and purpose between all people and the government-sponsored Basic Schools. The concerns and priorities of irradicating poverty, untouchability, and economic disparaties, and doing so by dispensing the right kind of education required the dedication and commitment of the government and the leadership. Competing goals and the availability of options, however, rendered Basic Education non- viable. The main obstacles to the success of Basic Education in obtaining the goals sought of individual and social transformation are generally viewed to be the following: apathy, lack of commit- ment of teachers and administrators; distrust on the part of people concerning the goals of Basic Education, and other traditional and cultural factors such as community attitudes and perceptions con- cerning Basic Schools. Other shortcomings are described as administrative--poor curriculum planning, teacher education and lack of sufficient research. In addition to the internal reasons for the lack of success of Basic Education, a number of incongruities became evident between the goals and values sought from Basic Education, and the leaders' perceptions and goals for Indian society generally. Gandhian ideals of communitarian, self-sufficient village society were opposed to national goals of industrialization and Westernization. Gandhi's ideas of casteless, classless, cooperative, homogeneous society met with opposition and resistance from local, traditional elites. While Basic Education had its own band of committed followers, many 139 of those in charge of instituting the program were themselves elites: administrative, intellectual, and political. They were Westernized or harbored plans of Westernization for their own children. Even committed administrative elites had to reach masses of people through local elites who exercised economic, political, and cultural controls over the landless, rural poor, and they undermined any effort to change the status quo radically. Once the political realities had redefined Basic Education and emasculated it of its economic and cultural dimensions, what remained was nothing more than an attempt to pursue development through the educational transformation of individual psyches. There are some obvious divergences between McClelland and Gandhi and in the type of educational programs devised. McClelland focuses on specific groups and ignores the masses while Gandhi concentrates on the masses of rural poor. McClelland is concerned with a specific psychological propensity and its effect on develop- ment and growth, and Gandhi is concerned with the total existential situation of man and his relationship to God, society, and other men. They do, however, converge with respect to the notion of individual transformation, by advocating that the transformation of the rural masses on the one hand, and urban entrepreneurs on the other will eventually lead to further social change. Nevertheless, there are a number of significant divergent points of view which become evident when one examines the type of social change envisioned and the goals each hoped to achieve through individual transformation. F I”: 9 5 1 i. . u.’ '1 \ e1 140 Manifest in McClelland's educational program for instituting social change are some Western assumptions and orientations concerning the kind of change, the direction of change, and how it can be delivered. In spite of the obvious individualistic psychological orientation he professes, the concepts of modernity, growth, and development occupy a central place. Change in psychological states of individuals, as viewed in the McClelland perspective occurs gfitpjp_the framework of growth and development. It implies that growth is good, especially if it is reflected in and through industrial production, and ideally within the framework of private enterprise, wrapped in the ideology of individualism. It is exactly in the area of assumptions of social change that Gandhi's views are diametrically opposed to McClelland's. The difference is not just in degree and rate of change, or levels of development, but it is a difference in the kjpg_of development to be pursued. The indicators for Gandhi, are neither growth, moderniza- tion nor industrialization, nor are they universalism as opposed to ascription, modernity opposed to tradition, or similar pattern variables of attitudes, values, and behaviors that define the per- sonality of the traditional man as opposed to modern man. Gandhi's concerns lay with devising ways and means for solving the overriding and urgent problems facing Indian society. His aim was to obtain equality for all, and in the case of India this meant the village-dwelling masses. Both in the analysis of the problems and their solutions he assigned primary position to indi- viduals. It was the condition of people that was of immediate I41 concern, and it was through them and by them that solutions were to be implemented. The people who mattered were not a select few-- entrepreneurs or businessmen. It was violence and the exploitation of man by man which distressed Gandhi. He sought to overcome both by advocating individual transformation of attitudes, values, and motives, by the use of determined persuasion, and conversion to the principles of non-violence and truth and love, by changing men's inner environment. Society could not be considered good unless individual men were good. It was through a process of self-purification that social change occurred. Moreover, the progress of the soul could be achieved only through service of society. There is a strain toward consistency between the ideal and the real, with the real submerged in the ideal. At a fundamental level, social change for Gandhi meant the creation of a better society, and for McClelland it meant a more modern one. Both considered that education would transform indi- viduals toward following the right direction in guaranteeing social change. Concluding_Remarks The major concern in this study has been to explicate a particular perspective within social science-~described as the individualistic approach--in explanation of social change; and by drawing upon two educational programs from the Indian context to analyze the psychological individualistic orientations embedded in them. 142 Within social science there have been two diametrically opposed views concerning the causal relationship between individual and society. Explanation in the case of one proceeds from the perspective of individual psychological states--needs, knowledge, values, motives, desires, and interests; and in the other case by reference to society as embodied in particular institutions and expressed in and through particular norms and rules for conduct that constrain and, in turn, are viewed as determining individual action. One is described as "methodological individualism" and the other as "holism" (see Chapter II). It is the former approach which has been the subject Of this study. Within social science both approaches have been profitably used to explore and explain social phenomena, and continue to be so used, but in their extreme forms both perspectives express a mechanistic logic of causation: one implies that the individual acting as a social being determines society, and the other, society constituting the structural conditions of social action determines the behavior of individuals. Formal logic demands that one be the subject and the other the predicate of causal statements. Both can- not be subject and object at the same time. But formal logic is inadequate, because neither the individual nor society is prior to the other. Both exist simultaneously in the dialectical unity of the human situation, each affecting the other (Alavi). Social life is the outcome of "a dialectical process of externalization, objectivation, and internalization" (Zijderveld, 1971:159). There are "three dialectical moments" in the social construction of 143 reality. These are: "Society is a human product. Society is an . objective reality. Man is a social product" (Berger and Luckmann, 1967:61). An analysis of the social world must take all three into consideration. To disregard any gpe_is to distort reality and present only a partial and one-sided picture. However, as Brodbeck points out, since social theory is still in a rudimentary state, one can either advocate a particular theory or approach, wait for further developments in sociology or psychology, or act upon one's "own psychological hunches." The issue, however, is "not to recommend methodological license, only methodological liberty for the social scientist to find his laws and explanations where he may" (Brodbeck, 1954:156). Rather than entering into a metaphysical discourse on the dialectical perspective, I shall attempt to incorporate the method in a discussion of the relationship between individualistic psycho- logical approaches and education. Education conceptualized as an enterprise which is institu- tionalized, can be viewed as involving the co-activity of a group of individuals displaying specific relationships having their activity aimed at specific goals and justified by a particular rationale or ideology. Some of the functions of education as an institutionalized process are socialization, enculturation and identity formation of individuals. But these aims of education are not unique to education as a formal institutional enterprise. - Family, peer group, and other institutions to which individuals belong, may perform similar functions. Moreover, the demands of 144 institutions may contradict one another. The basis of an individual's actions is his subjective cognition of the objective reality. Indi- vidual action will be affected by the degree of knowledge or ignorance on his part and imperfections of foresight as well as the simultaneous actions of others (Alavi; Wilhelm, 1967; Murphy, 1971). It is not only idealistic to assume that all socializing agents and institutions, including educational institutions, will be synchronized in their efforts to create in individuals similar values, desires, motives, and attitudes with respect to particular ends, whether these are economic growth and development or the promotion of a peaceful and non-violent society. It is also futile to expect all individuals to respond alike to a particUlar educa- tional input. Inherent in human interaction is a dualism. "This dualism lies at the very roots of human action, and places in all men, in all cultures, an internal conflict that is perduring and inescapable" (Goldschmidt, 1966:42). Institutions provide codes for behavior and constrain action, even though all individuals do not necessarily conform to them. There are variations in the ways people go about satisfying their needs. But the alternatives that individuals choose from are not accidental or random in nature, they are determined by the existing conditions in society (Alavi; Wilhelm, 1967). Explanations for variation in individual behaviors cannot be provided only by reference to individual psychological states. Social life is the product of more than individual psycholo- gies, it cannot be adequately understood by reference to individual motivations and desires alone. 145 In the realm of education, as an institutional enterprise, it is impossible to deny the importance of ideas, norms, and codes for conduct, on the one hand, and individual motives, desires, needs and interests on the other. Educators are in the very center of the business of inculcating ideas and manipulating individuals to conform to and internalize socially desirable ends, while at the same time they are concerned with variations in needs--biological, psychological and functional--of each child. First, educators have, at least at an analytical level, the obligation and responsibility to be aware of the range of capacities, and variations in the ability to perform tasks from one individual to another. This is not to be construed to mean that some are better than others. People have varying traits and these are expressed in each to varying degrees, and they do not necessarily run together in the same individual (Goldschmidt, 1966). But certain biological and psycho- logical needs do require fulfillment in all individuals--the need for survival, protection, and positive affect--before learning can take place. However, in the consideration of educational needs a valuation of ends is involved. For example, a child may want some- thing and go about getting it; he may need something and may not know that the lack of it is desirable. Needs imply a lack of some- thing, and that lack is determined by educational ends (Hirst and Peters, 1970). However, the explanation for the determination of educational aims cannot be provided exclusively by individual needs. Similarly, explanations for change or lack of it in individual behaviors cannot I46 exclusively be by reference to innate capacities. The Intelligence Quotient as a measure of individual capacities, for example, tends to lump together "a variety of undefined traits" (Goldschmidt, 1966: 45). Differences in abilities may be the result of a number of factors--1ack of skills, government action, laws, the associations and groups individuals belong to. In any case, it is not solely dependent upon individual capacities. Second, the process of learning involves not only the learn- ing of knowledge, skills, and training for occupation, but it also requires an understanding of the culturally prescribed rewards and punishments operating in a situation. A teacher cannot with impunity ignore the institutional and normative constraints in the form of "standards for social conduct" (Wilhelm, 1967), or the application of dominant norms of achievement and success that impinge upon individual action. To take external factors for granted is to concede to them uncritically or accept them as good and desirable. If institutional arrangements are taken as given, the problem becomes one of changing individuals to conform to the goals and ends of specific institutions, or a similar conformity is demanded to some abstract and idealized goals of economic growth and development; or a solution to basic social and economic problems is sought by seek- ing individual conversion and commitment to abstract principles, for example, truth and non-violence. In either case, there is a denial of conflict or opposition of interests; a natural harmony of interests is assumed. Individual volition-~"deliberation in the sense of compliance or non-compliance" I47 (Wilhelm, 1967) in action is denied. The assumption is that the right type of education will harness individual volition to the good of one and all. Implicit in this view is a static conception of society in which everything is in a state of harmony and equilibrium which contradicts the very notion of change that is being attempted. While straining to recognize individual autonomy in action there is capitulation in favor of societal correlates expressed to particularly in an ideology which becomes embedded in an educational : idiom. Not only are the multiplicity of social processes involved I ' in action ignored, but there may also be options in the ideals people profess. Variations in the extent to which individuals express commitment to ideals is denied. The gap between ideal standards and actual conduct is viewed as deviant, and the problem becomes one of bringing individual activity into conformity with the standards. If, however, the societal correlates which circumscribe action are examined and their adequacy questioned--rules of authority structure, power relations, institutional arrangements--the danger, in the consideration 0f the social dimension within the framework of the individualistic psychological approaches, is to label force, authority, and power as bad and coercive. Analysis tends to be normative without being empirical. The solution sought is that authority, power, and force must be removed because they are bad. The individual must be "liberated" from these external forces, and permitted to seek self-realization. The search, then, is to seek out an "ideal" environment, in which the child can be protected and I48 insulated from the corrupting influences of the adult world (Skidelsky, 1969). The dilemma of the human situation is that men participate in institutions created by other men, and although individuals leave, the institutions continue. The "actualization of man's nature" occurs "through the incorporation of the objects of the external world," but no single person can assimilate all of it, with the result that the external world "becomes oppressive, incomprehensible, and estranged" (Murphy, 1971:132). Conflict and contradictions between individual predilections and inclinations and institutional demands are characteristic of the human situation. Ideology and action coalesce only when a total revo1ution is envisioned which replaces the old ideology: . the basis of revolution is the self-consciousness of a class, as such, and a consciousness of the true interests of the members of a class. This grasp of Truth is not realized mechanically but comes about through conscious revolutionary activity--the attainment of true—EEIf:-——' consciousness is predicated upon struggle . . . (Murphy, 1971:100). Or change may be grindingly slow, as conflict and contradictions are contained ". . . by enormous elasticity in the system of social action, allowing the actors to thread their way through the culture rather than conform to its norms . . . (1971:224). To narrow the analysis to the relationship between education and change, because the inherent focus of any educational enterprise is upon direct manipulation and transformation of individuals, the tendency in implementing change is to favor individual transformation. The notion of change is based more on an "optimistic philosophy of human 149 nature" than on observed behavior and the multiplicity of the social processes involved. Such attempts, however, are conservative since, by default or because of the choice of the particular model of social change, they take the existing conception of social order as inevitably given. In any case, congruence between individual motives and values and the desired ends from education is assumed. Gandhi, for instance, attempted to merge the real and the ideal. His own life was a symbol of conscious revolutionary activity, a series of "Experiments with Truth." He sought self- realization through active participation in the world. But the supra-human efforts of one man not only to seek self-realization but to institutionalize an ideology refracted into idolatry and dogma, and become a new orthodoxy, as in the case of Basic Education. BIBLIOGRAPHY 150 BIBLIOGRAPHY ABERLE, DAVID F. 1961 "Culture and Socialization." In Psychological Anthropology. Edited by Francis L. K. Hsu. PP. 381- 399. Homewood, 111.: The Dorsey Press Inc. ADAVAL, S. 8. (ed.) 1968 The Third Indian Yearbook of Education: Educational Research. New Delhi: National’CounciT 6f Educational Research and Training. AGEHANANDA, BHARATI 1968 "Great Tradition" and "Little Tradition": An Anthro- pological View of Eastern Societies. Anthropological Backgrounds on Adult Education. Boston: CEhter fer the Study of Liberal Education for Adults 57:72-94. 1970 "The Hindu Renaissance and its Apologetic Patterns." The Journal of Asian Studies (February 29, 1970), 267- 2872 ALAVI , HAMZA 1975 "India and the Colonial Mode of Production." Economic and Political Weekly, Special Number 10:33-35. n.d. "Political Structures and Economic Development in Rural West Pakistan." Mimeograph, p. 43. ANDRESKI, STANISLAV 1972 Social Science as Sorcery. New York: St. Martin's Press. APTE. M. D. 1975 ”Education and Unemployment in Kerala." Economic and Political Weekly lO(28):1040-1042. ARAN, LYDIA: EISENSTADT, S. N.: and ADLER, CHAIM. 1972 "The Effectiveness of Educational Systems in the Processes of Modernization." Comparative Education Review, l6(l):30-43. AVINASHILINGAM, CHETTIAR T. S. 1964 "Birth and Growth of Basic Education (1931-1961)." The Second Indian Yearbook of Education: Elementagy Education. New Delhi: NatibnalTCouncil of Educational Research and Training. 151 Tau—WM}. L-A [Ir 152 BALWANTRAI MEHTA COMMITTEE 1964 "Democratic Decentralization." The Second Indian Year- book of Education: Elementary Education. New’Delhi: NationaT'Council of’EdUcationalTResearch and Training. BEATTIE, JOHN 1964 Other Cultures: Aims, Methods and Achievements of Social—Anthiopoifigy. Neinfirk: The Free Press. BERGER, PETER, and LUCKMANN, THOMAS 1966 The Social Construction of Reality. New York: Anchor Books. BETEILLE, A. 1969 Castes, Old and New. Essays in Social Structure and SociaT'Stratification. New—YORK: Asia—PUblishing House. . BISWAS, ARABINDA and AGRAWAL, SURESH (eds.) 1971 Indian Educational Documents Since Independence. Committees, Commissions, Canerences. _New Delhi: The Academic PubliShers. BLAUGH, MARK 1970 An Introduction to the Economics of Education. MiddTesex, England: Penguifi Books. BOSE, NIRMAL KUMAR 1967 Culture and Society in India. Bombay: Asia Publishing House. BRODBECK. MAY 1954 "On the PhilOSOphy of the Social Sciences." Philosophy of Science 21(2):l40-156. 1954 "Methodological Individualisms: Definition and Reduction." Philosophy of Science 25(1):l-22. 1968 Readings in the Philosophy of the Social Sciences (ed.). London: ‘MacmiTTan Co. BRODBECK, MAY and FEIGL, HERBERT (eds.) 1953 Readings in the Philosophy of Science. New York: AppTeton-Century-Crofts, Inc. BROWN, ROBERT 1963 Explanation in Social Science. Chicago: Aldine Publishing Company. CURLE. ADAM 1973 Education for Liberation. London: Tavistock Publishers. 153 DANDEKAR, V. M. and RATH, N. 1971 "Poverty in India: Policies and Pro rammes. I and II." Economic and Political Weekly, 6(1&ZI DESAI, A. R. (ed.) 1969 Rural Sociology in India. Bombay: Popular Prakashan. DUBE, S. C. 1958 India's Changinngillages. Human Factors in Community Developmentli_London: RoutTedge and Kegan Paul, Ltd} DUMONT, LOUIS - 1964 "Change, Interaction, and Comparison." Contributions to Indian Sociology 7:7-17. - 1965 "The Modern Conception of the Individual. Notes on its Genesis." Contributions to Indian Sociology_le3-6l. 1970 Homo Hierarchieus. The Caste System and Its Implications. Trans. by Mark—Bainsbury. Chicago: *University of Chicago Press. DURKHEIM, EMILE 1964 The Rules of Sociological Method. New York: The Free Press Edition. EISENSTADT, S. N. 1963 "The Need for Achievement." Economic Development and Cultural Change_11(4):420-431. ELMHURST, LEONARD 1968 "Rabindranath Tagore and Sriniketan." In Evaluation of Community Development Programmes in India. New Delhi: Department of CommuhityTDevelopment, Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Community Development and Cooperation. FOSTER, GEORGE M. . 1965 "Peasant Society and the Ima e of Limited Good." American Anthropologist 66(ZI:293-315. FRANK, ANDRE G. 1972 "Sociology of Development and Underdevelopment of Sociology." In Dependence and Underdevelopment. Edited by J. Cockcroft, A. G. Frank and D. L. Johnson. New York: Anchor Books. FRASER, THOMAS M. 1968 Culture and Change in India. Amherst: 'University of Massachusetts‘Press. 154 FREIRE, PAULO 1972 Pedagogy of the Oppressed. New York: Herder and Herder. GALBRAITH, JOHN K. 1973 Economics and the Public Purpose. Boston: Houghton MiffTin Company. GANDHI, M. K. 1962 The Problem of Education. Ahmedabad: The Navajivan PublishingTHouse. 1962 Basic Education. Ahmedabad: The Navajivan Publishing House. 1957 The Story of My Emperiments with Truth. An Autobiography. Boston: BeaconTPress. 1941 Economics of Khadi. Ahmedabad: The Navajivan Publishing House. 1939. Basic National Education. Report of the Zakir Husain Committee and the Detailed Syllabus. Wardha: Hindustani Talimi Sangh. GEERTZ, CLIFFORD 1973 The Interpretation of Cultures. New York: Basic Books, Inc. GEZI, KALIL I..(ed.) 1971 Education in Comphrative and International Perspectives. New York} Holt, Rinehart andTWihston, Inc. GOHEEN, JOHN; SRINIVAS, M. N., KARVE, D. G. and SINGER, MILTON 1958 "India's Cultural Values and Economic Development: A Discussion." Economic Development and Cultural Development 7(1):TL12.T7’ GOLDSCHMIDT, WALTER 1959 Man's Way; A Preface to the Understanding_of Human Society. ‘nen—vbrk: *Holt,TRinehart and Winston, Inc. 1966 Comparative Functionalism. Los Angeles: University of CaliforniaiPress. GRANDSTAFF, MARVIN (ed.) 1974 Historical Perspectives on Non-formal Education. East Lansing: MiEhigan State UniVersity Program Of'Studies in Non-formal Education Team Reports. I55 GRUNBAUM, ADOLF 1953 "Causality and the Science of Human Behavior." In Readings in the Philosophy of Science, pp. 766-778. Edited"by MT'BrodBeEk andTH. FeigT} New York: Appleton- Century-Crofts, Inc. GUPTA, K. P. 1971 "A Theoretical Approach to Hinduism and Modernization." The Indian Journal of Sociology 2(1):59-91. 1971 "Socio-Cultural Determinants." Seminar: China Today (September) 21-25. HANSON, A. H. 1966 The Process of Planning; A Stugy_of India's Five-Year Plans 1950;1965T’ Neinork: OxfordTUniversity Press. HARBISON, F. H. and MYERS, C. A. 1969 "Strategies of Human Resource Development." In Economics of Education. II. Selected Essays. Edited by M. Gleugh. Middlesex, Englandii Penguin Books. HARRIS, MARVIN 1968 The Rise of Anthropological Theohy. A History of Theories of Culture. 'New"York: Thomas V. Crowéll Co. HIRST, PAUL and PETERS, R. S. 1970 The Logic of Education. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. HOMANS, GEORGE C. 1964 "Bringing Men Back In." American Sociological Review 29(5):809-818. HOLT, ROBERT and TURNER, JOHN T. 1966 The Political Basis of Economic Development. New York: o.*ven Nostrand Co. INKELES, ALEX 1966 "The Modernization of Man." In Modernization: The thamics of Growth. Edited by Myron Neiner. New York: Basic BoOEE, Inc. JOSHI, P. C. 1970 "The Relevance of Gandhi for Indian Development." Ihe_ Indian Journal of Sociology_l(2):l39-152. KOSHY, T. A. 1968 "Research in Basic and Social Education." In The Third Indian Yearbook of Education: Educational Research. New DeThi?‘ National Council of Educational Research and Training. 156 KOTHARI, RAJNI 1972 "Political Economy of Garibi Hatao." Economic and Political Weekly 7(Specia1 Number):154l-1552. KRIPALANI, J. B. 1938 The Latest Fad. Wardha: Hindustani Talimi Sangh. Sevagram. KUNKEL, JOHN 1963 "Psychological Factors in the Analysis of Economic DevelOpment." Journal of Social Issues 19(1):68-87. 1965 "Values and Behavior in Economic Development." Economic Develppment and Cultural Change 13(3):257-277. 1970 Society and Economic Growth: A Behavioral Perspective ofTSociaT‘Change. ‘New York: Oxford University Press. LASKA, JOHN A. - 1968 Planning and Educational Development in India. New Yerk: ‘Columbia Teachers College Press. LeVINE, ROBERT A. 1966 Dreams and Deeds Achievement Motivation in Nigeria. Chicago: The University of Chieago'Press. LERNER, DANIEL 1958 The Passing of Traditional Society. New York: The Free—Press. LEWIS. JOHN P. 1964 Quiet Crisis in India. Economic Development and American Polity. New Yehk: TAnChor Books. LEWIS, OSCAR 1970 Anthropological Essays. New York: Random House. LIPTON, MICHAEL 1968 "Strategy for Agriculture: Urban Bias and Rural Planning." In The Crisis of Indian Plannihg, Edited by Paul Streeten and MiEhael'Lipton. TNew York: Oxford University Press. MACHENZIE-BROWN, o. ' 1959 The White Umbrella: Indian Political Thought from Manu to Gahdhi) Berkeley: Uhiversity of California Press. 1961 The Nationalist Movement: Indian Political Thogght from Ranade to Bhave. Beerley: University of Califorhia Press. 157 McCLELLAND, DAVID C. 1961 The Achieving Society. Princeton, N.J.: D. Van Nostrahd‘Co. 1963 "Motivational Patterns in Southeast Asia with Special Reference to the Chinese Case." Journal of Social Issues 19:6-19. 1966 "The Impulse to Modernization." In Modernization the Dynamics of Growth. Edited by Myron WEiher. New Yerk: Basic Books, Inc. McCLELLAND, DAVID C and WINTER, DAVID C. (eds.) 1969 Motivating Economic Achievement. New York: The Free Press. MBDA,J.S. ; 1964 "Democratic Decentralization." In The Second Indian Yearbook of Education: Elementary Education. New Delhi: ’National Council of’EducationaTTResearch and Training. MILLS, C. WRIGHT 1958 The Sociological Imagination. New York: Oxford University Press. MORRIS-JONES. W. H. 1960 "The Unhappy Utopia--J.P. in Wonderland." Economic and Political Week1y_12(26). MURPHY, ROBERT F. 1971 The Dialectics of Social Life: Alarms and Excursions in Anthropoiogieal Theory. NewTYork: Basic Books, Inc. MYRDAL, GUNNAR 1970 The Challenge of World Poverty. New York: Vintage Books. NAIR, KUSUM 1969 The Lonely Furrow: Farming in the United States, Japan and Thdie. Ann ArBBr: University of MiEhigan Press. 1973 Ihree Bowls of Rice. India and Japan: Century of Effort. "East Lansihg: MiEhigan State University Press. 158 NANDY, ASHIS 1973 “Need Achievement in a Calcutta Suburb." In Entrepre- neurship and Modernization of Occupational Cultures in South”Asia.i‘EditedTby Milton Singer. DUFham, NlCi} Duke University Program in Comparative Studies in Southern Asia Monograph 12:167-178. NISBET, ROBERT A. 1969 Social Change and History. Aspects of the Western Theory_ef”Development. NeinorkE Oxford University Press. NOVAK, GEORGE ._, 1968 Empiricism and Its Evolution: A Marxist View. New ' YorkziiMerit’PubliShers. OSTERGAARD, GEOFFREY and CURRELL, MELVILLE 4" 1971 The Gentle Anarchists. A Stqu of the Sarvodeya Move- ment for NonJViolent_Rev61ution in India. iLondbn: Oxford University‘Press. POCOCK, DAVID F. 1961 "Psychological Approaches and Judgments of Reality." Contributions to Indian Sociology_5:44-74. PRASAD, BIMLA (ed.) 1964 Socialism, Sarvodaye, and Democracy. Selected Works of JayaprakeehTNarayan. TBombay: ASia PubliShing House. RAMJI, M. T. 1969 The Concept of Personality in the Educational Thought of MEhatma Cahdhi. NewiDelhi: National Countil Dir EdfieetibhET—Research and Training. 1970 "Promotion of Gandhian Values in Indian Education." In International Education Yearbook: Seminar on Primagy» and'WBrkJDriented'Education. New—Delhi: National Council ofTEducationET Research and Training. RIVETT, KENNETH 1959 "The Economic Thought of Mahatma Gandhi." The British Journal of Sociology_lO(l):l-15. ROGERS, EVERETT M. 1968 "Mass Media Exposure and Modernization Among Colombian Peasants." In Mass Communication and the Development of Nations. East Lan§ingz Mithigan State University International Communications Institute 3:1-19. 1962 Diffusion of Innovations. New York: Free Press. 159 RUDOLPH, SUSANNE H. 1961 "Consensus and Conflict in Indian Politics." World Politics 13(3):385-399. RUDOLPH, LLOYD I. and RUDOLPH, SUSANNE H. 1967 The Modernity of Tradition. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. SALAMATULLAH 1964 "Basic Education: Retrospect and Prospect." In [he- Second Yearbook of Education: Elementary Education. New Delhi: National Council oirEducationaTPResearch and Training. 1970 “Relevance of Basic Education to Contemporary India." In International Education Year Seminar on Primary and Work-OrientedTEdUCation. “New DElhi: NationaTTCouncil of EdUcationaT’Research‘and Training. SAU, RANJIT 1972 "The 'New Economics.'" Economic and Political Weekly. 7(Special Number):157l-1580. SCHUMACHER, S. C. 1973 Small is Beautiful: Economics As If Pe0p1e Mattered. New Y6rk3’_HarperTTorch606ks. SEN, LALIT K. 1973 "The Concepts of Tradition and Modernity: A Re- Evaluation." Behavioral Sciences and Community Develop- Ment 7(2):83-105. SINGER, MILTON 1966 "Religion and Social Change in India: The Max Weber Thesis Phase Three." hppnomic Development and Cultural Change l4(4):497-505. 1972 When a Great Tradition Modernizes. An Anthropological Approach to Indian'Civilization. New York: Praeger Publishers. 1973 Entrepreneurship and Modernization of Occppational Cultures in South Asia—Ted.) Durham, NYC}: Duke UniVersity Program ih'Comparative Studies on Southern Asia Monograph. SINGH, S. MOHINDERA 1957 "The Ideology and Practice of Basic Education." In ggucation and Philosophy: The Yearbook of Education. Editediby G. Z.’Bereday and JI—A. [auwerys. New—YOFk: Worldbook Company. I60 SKIDELSKY, ROBERT 1969 English Progressive Schools. Middlesex, England: Pengfiih_Bo6ks:TLtd. SRINIVAS, M. N. 1975 "Village Studies, Participant Observation and Social Research in India." Economic and Political Weekly 10(Specia1 Numberzl387-1394: STENT, GUNTHER S. 1975 "Limits to the Scientific Understanding of Man." Science 187(4181):1052-1057. SWAMY, SUBRAMANIAN 1973 "Economic Growth in China and India, 1952-1970. A Comparative Appraisal." Economic Development and Cultural Change 21(4). TINKER, HUGH 1964 "Magnificent Failure? The Gandhian Ideal in India After Sixteen Years." International Affairs 40(2): 262—276. TURNER, JONATHAN H. 1972 American Societerroblems of Structure. New York: Harper and Row PUBTishers. VALENTINE, CHARLES A. 1968 Culture and Poverry} Critiques and Counter-Proposals. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. WEISSKOPF, WALTER A. 1950 "Individualism and Economic Theory." The American Journal of Economics and Sociology 9(3 : - 1949 "Psychological Aspects of Economic Thought.“ Journal ‘ of Political Economy 42:304. WHITE. LESLIE ' 1949 The Science of Culture: A Study of Man and Civilization. New York: "Grove—Press, Inc. WICKER, ALLAN W. 1969 "Attitudes Versus Actions: The Relationship of Overt Behavioral Responses to Attitude Objects." Journal of Social Issues 25(4):41-78. WILHELM, SIDNEY M. 1967 "A Reformulation of Social Action Theory." The American Journal of Economics and Sociology 26(1):23-31. 161 WRONG, DENNIS 1961 "The Oversocialized Concept of Man." American Sociological Review 26:183-193. ZEITLIN, IRVING M. 1968 Ideology and the Development of Sociological Theory, Englewdfid’CTiffEttN.J.: Prentice Hall}tInc. ZIJDERVELD, ANTON 1970 The Abstract Sociery, New York: Doubleday and Company. ZACHARIAH, MATHEW 1970 "Public Authority and Village Reconstruction: The Case of Basic Education in India." The Journal of Educational Thouoht 4(2):94-106. . . .1...) 1!" I .I ul ., ER “11111111111111illiililliliillil“