:WW’ -- «PF . I. “I 1:3": I): .1“. ' ' 4 "iii. {l,,‘V’|':"‘ A v -:8:'-;. 3‘ u '0'“- fl "' v“. “3&1.” “<1 5 ( .' “'4 ‘rt “In Fig 5'"? . ‘H'II'. .‘I [2" Iii." ‘% "Li; ggffiflw.‘ I l ‘ 3W m « (in? 6“ - ' ‘1' ['0’ 32%;; {ER - Q‘Xfl'kw. ‘(MC‘K‘ d‘me‘L M \g. . \Jmfg J . l" ' I | lg“ " ' "in J 2"” L" . Vfifiguu ‘ " . \‘IJQ. t. . . ‘ FIN»? 3|“ 7"}! ~H‘ -‘ - A” 1”)" 0: 05‘). “‘3' ":- ':,.- ‘. :9» = : ~». -~ :: : :r ,: . *7: .. It” ”(‘2 "1);“ I @A' gin" \I‘y‘q‘lJ \l. JR??? 93‘!“ ,0 ‘ "I “‘31-” . I I A. . ‘ u 1' .' I ‘ .5 '-'- m3)? “CM: ‘fg’xfi'f'fi {8%}? a. t 3" 'v. ' ' | K I‘ ‘0 :“\~ A” At ‘2‘ " g! :‘52: M: A ._ _ :1 :3. ‘ - —-~p.4} Q t‘ v ‘ .. '5 u\' . I , ”:93,- l . ~ v.31, '1‘“ 1' ._ .1 J \' ”:0 tr..." 53.1,‘14 ‘ I ”.7. ‘ “ii/3.: u... ' U | ) ~ if" (b"“g::&::::v‘; (3%». IQ‘.I'I“-€lu 4:" ’6“ 3.4.1“ .1 ’I . I: 32..“ m" “3 .; ""“mgqsf‘”231':'.I'H"b‘,"g§-L': ‘ 1 3( WWx‘b‘ 3‘ :1: :‘27' "'” ‘7 1‘: Q‘ ‘1‘: My: ' :e:* :‘::':=-;;:- :p‘: ::v:::*»'::~:.»°--:: ' ‘ ”'7“; ‘ """' :" " fi'l'l‘i'}. ". '." t .- r-‘n . p.363»; 1.)? ' , '1»: 'h \2 - :‘vMfi 2-2», 't. m ":7":- 11 ": 7 ID ;,-,: ..' do .. (”‘JMMJH '9J ‘ high -’ I . .r.l " .3 I '. lI : 0" .“\.' ' ” ::" 0”” ‘I’n ‘ . «:-.:.::»:~-- 33:: ,. I \ (' .A'I , . I I ‘1 \ ‘jfl ' :IIOIJ O“? y'l'l ' u I’!‘:' 3’.“ v‘flk‘ l |;,':{\:"r II “AX ‘ V. ‘:I...IU‘~ M «:3: :- IA' .gv'j; #J‘“ 94" .‘L‘N‘LSH {W R‘“ "If! 'Ii ‘1‘“! {’3‘ IQ), - ' h; '3 4hr“; ' I Q‘N‘HI. AK“ M' ‘ti’f‘ ICE: WNW ."'}§9’-\:;. uC.‘ ' ‘ "J‘z'ai‘f'w" ‘” J’hfl "‘ 953’ “}'~3.‘.".:7'5"I'§.:i 731:”.0'2". : i: ”1:; :‘\\7{'\.31?’ffl° " .,::f. ~ 6 ~ . 27:11::9“ :T‘H’“ 72:2...- : v.;-:-.:;~ ....-: w. ... m. .. : 71$ . , \ .. ‘ u: . . I r. a. ‘ cv. . --,' .> “'3 ‘ ’:‘ l‘ ’ ' giix'éyf-u-I ' fl . ,Ia,,.' {fur}. if. 50‘: 'nf‘u‘“ " ' x . - ";,- ‘o . '3 : 3‘ . .“.'-' (. ‘W' V " -u- ‘ I-‘\""u"y'$ ' M? 76;“; - ~ .. 1}.“ \I-' 1 u II _|’ .. ‘_ lq'. “Ml-Z. ' . ., {'3‘ \ JI .1 :' “J‘s/F.“ I . 7 7 , JL ‘ , . . ‘ . : {K :\'-.‘- an: : :44" 1:33.. 'r. m, .f.ff.:3,},‘bz..:~':y J :11“: ' ~01”: ALL... 3). A This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Pricing Behavior in the Deregulated Motor Carrier Industry; An Empirical Investigation presented by Harwood Hoover, Jr. has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Marketing MSU Lt an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 MSU LIBRARIES m ‘- RETURNING MATERIALS: Piace in book drop to remove this checkout from your record. FINES wiii be charged if book is returned after-the date stamped beiow. PRICING BEHAVIOR IN THE DEREGULATED MOTOR CARRIER INDUSTRY; AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION By Harwood Hoover, Jr. A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Marketing and Transportation Administration 1984 Copyright by Harwood Hoover, Jr. 1984 ABSTRACT PRICING BEHAVIOR IN THE DEREGULATED MOTOR CARRIER INDUSTRY; AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION By Harwood Hoover, Jr. The motor carrier act of 1980 allowed motor carriers substantial new pricing freedoms, and reduced constraints upon market entry. This act (nIhninated a period of academic and political debate concerning the outcomes of such a substantial policy change. A central theoretical issue in this debate was the applicability of the competitive economic model. Strong arguments were made to the effect that all segments of the industry would not, in fact respond competitively. Less than truckload carriers, operationalized as carriers of general conmodities with substantial terminal investments, might be expected to react with increasing concentration and eventual departure from competitive pricing behavior. This research examined whether or not the pricing behavior of’ifliis carrier group was conforming to Specific competitive expectations. The conformity of carrier behavior to the expectations of the Stigler theory of economic regulation was also examined. The Stigler theory would expect that regulation benefited, and therefore was supported by, the carriers. TO examine carrier pricing behavior, a mail survey was conducted with presidents of firms in the identified carrier group. Seven hundred and thirty-two presidents of regular route connion carriers of general commodities were surveyed. One hundred and eighty-five useful responses were subjected to data analysis. Harwood Hoover, Jr. This carrier group was found to be making greater use of tariffs than of contracts, but to be individualizing their rate behavior through the use of special tariffs or Special items aimed at one or a few shippers. Carriers were engaging in discounting, and reported changes in their revenue cost relationships such that prices were closer to costs. The cross subsidy situation was reported to be changing, but the carrier group reported that the cross subsidy of shipments which were losing money prior to deregulation continues. They also report that powerful shippers are negotiating prices closer to the carriers costs than other shippers have been able to do. Carriers are innovating by adopting certain marketing perspectives and by adding service to new geographic areas. Substantial heterogeneity of pricing behavior was documented, and support for the Stigler perspective was found. TO MY HIF E CAROL ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This research could not have been completed without the help and guidance of several important people. I gratefully acknowledge the aid, guidance and encouragement of these individuals. To Dr. Donald A. Taylor, former Chairman of the Department of Marketing and Transportation and chairman of my dissertation committee, I express my heartfelt thanks for his initial encouragement of my decision to enter the program, his understanding of my need to keep my home while pursuing my education, and his role as effective coordinator and team leader for the dissertation project. TO Dr. John L. Hazard, Professor of Transportation and former Assistant Secretary of Transportation, I express my gratitude for his role as mentor. Professor Hazard's inspiring personal example, com- tfining the highest levels of professional and academic accomplishment with the subtle and unselfish influence of a teacher will always be an inspiration to me. TO Dr. George D. Hagenheim, Associate Professor of Marketing and Transportation, I extend my thanks for his encouragement when it was most needed, his detailed understanding of the industry which allowed a careful targeting of the survey, and his practical help throughout the project. TO Dr. Forrest S. Carter, Associate Professor of Marketing, I wish to express my sincere appreciation for his great and conscientious effort. His clear logic, attention to detail, and impressive under- standing of survey research and statistical methods were of great help. TO Dr. Ronald Savitt, Chairperson and Professor, Department of Marketing and Transportation, I express my gratitude for his encourage- ment, his comments on an earlier draft, and his insights concerning industrial organization and the Stigler theory of economic regulation. To Dr. William Lazer, former Professor of Marketing at Michigan State University, and the first chairman of the dissertation committee, I express my thanks fOr his hours of effort spent in the evaluation of earlier proposals, and his encouragement of this topic area. Finally, my deepest appreciation to my wife, Carol, who has stood beside me throughout this experience, typing my papers, enduring countless weekends devoted to the doctoral program, always providing encouragement. Neither this study nor any of my other accomplishments in the last fourteen years would have been possible without her. iv List of CHAPTER I. II. TABLE OF CONTENTS Figures .................................................... INTRODUCTION .............................................. Problem and General Approach .............................. Purpose and Research Questions ............................ Methodology ............................................... Limitations of the Study .................................. Contribution of the Study to Marketing .................... Organization ............................................. THE HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENT OF REGULATION IN THE MOTOR CARRIER INDUSTRY .......................................... Regulation of a Common Carrier ............................ Evolution of State Regulation ............................. Federal Policy ............................................ The Motor Carrier Act ..................................... Administration of the Act ................................. Other Major Legislation Affecting Trucking ................ The Debate ................................................ Arguments in Favor of Deregulation ........................ Innovation and Flexibility ................................ An Industry Competitively Structured ...................... Lower Rates and Adaptability to Economic Change ........... Lack of Economies of Scale; Failure to Meet Shipper Requirements .............................................. Dissatisfaction with Results and a Willingness to Experiment ................................................ The Costs and Feasibility of Regulation ................... Objections Discounted; Cross Subsidy, Chaos, Predation ..... Overseas Precedent ........................................ A Growing Consensus ....................................... Arguments Against Deregulation ............................ Price Discrimination ...................................... Loss of Specific Benefits ................................. Rate Chaos ................................................ Damage to Existing Carriers ............................... Non-Competitive Effects ................................... A Debate Summary .......................................... Administrative Deregulation ............................... The Legislative Process ................................... The Motor Carrier Act of 1980 ............................. Page xi 1 1 4 8 12 13 14 32 42 43 44 44 4o 47 48 49 III. THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS ........................ 59 Introduction .............................................. 59 Theoretical Analysis ...................................... 60 Economic Models ........................................... 60 The Competitive Pricing Model ............................. 61 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case ............ 61 Application: The Appropriateness of the Competitive Model. 62 Application: Problems With the Competitive Model ......... 63 Application: Competition, Oligopoly and the General Commodities Carrier ....................................... 64 Complementary Theoretical Perspectives .................... 65 Heterogeneity ............................................. 66 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case ............ 67 Portfolio Theory .......................................... 68 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case ............ 69 Pricing Perspectives ............................... , ....... 69 Price Defined ............................................. 69 Patterns of Corporate Pricing Behavior .................... 70 Perceived Price ........................................... 71 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case ............ 71 Issues in Regulatory Economics ............................ 72 The Research Focus in a Regulatory Context ................ 76 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case ............ 78 Summary: Theoretical Analysis ............................ 79 Empirical Analysis ........................................ 80 Evidence Suggesting Competitive Effects ................... 80 Industry Structure and Costs .............................. 80 Examinations of Deregulated Trucking and Comparisons With Regulated Trucking ................................... 81 Examinations of Overseas Experience ....................... 84 Observed Effects of MCA 1980 in Contemporary Literature ... 85 Summary: Evidence of Competitive Effects ................. 87 Evidence Suggesting Other Than Competitive Effects ........ 87 Problems with Competitive Assumptions ..................... 88 The Potential for Higher Rates ............................ 92 Overseas Experience ....................................... 94 Observed Effects of MCA 1980 in Contemporary Literature ... 94 Summary: Other Than Competitive Effects .................. 95 Evidence: Interest Groups and Regulation in Transportation ............................................ 95 Stigler ................................................... 96 Positions of Groups ....................................... 97 The Political Process ..................................... 99 Summary: Interest Groups and Regulation .................. 102 The Market Matching Process in the Motor Carrier Industry . 102 Evidence: The Market Matching Process .................... 103 The Study in the Context of the Literature ................ 104 vi IV. ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK AND RESEARCH DESIGN .................. 119 Introduction .............................................. 119 Research Framework ........................................ 119 Mail Survey: Instrument and Pretesting ................... 121 Sample and Sampling Method ................................ 122 Data Collection ........................................... 122 Data Analysis and the Purpose of the Research ............. 123 Data Analysis: Research Question 1A ...................... 129 Data Analysis: Research Question 18 ...................... 131 Data Analysis: Research Question 2A ...................... 131 Discounting Interpreted as Specific Discounts ............. 131 Price Cutting: Deviation from Bureau Tariffs ............. 132 Price Cutting: Relationship of Revenue to Costs .......... 133 Data Analysis: Research Question 28 ...................... 134 28: Discounting as Specific Discounts .................... 134 28: Discounting as Price Cutting: Deviation from Bureau Tariffs ............................................ 134 28: Discounting as Price Cutting: Relationship of Revenues to Costs ......................................... 135 28: Change Where Price Cutting is Seen as Either Specific Discounts or Price Reduction .............................. 135 Data Analysis: Research Question 3A ...................... 136 Data Analysis: Research Question 38 ...................... 136 Data Analysis: Research Question 4A ...................... 137 Data Analysis: Research Question 48 ...................... 138 Data Analysis: Taxonomy Development ...................... 139 Data Analysis: The Stigler Perspective ................... 141 Data Processing ........................................... 141 SUMMARY OF MAJOR FINDINGS ................................. 145 Introduction .............................................. 145 To What Extent is Carrier Pricing Behavior Characterized by the Use of Contracts vs. Tariffs? ...................... 145 Does Carrier Management See This as Constituting a Change Since Deregulation? ....................................... 145 To What Extent is Carrier Pricing Behavior Characterized by Extensive Discounting? ................................. 146 Specific Discounts ........................................ 147 Deviation from Bureau Tariffs ............................. 148 Relationship Of Revenues to Costs ......................... 148 Does Top Management See This as Constituting a Change Since Deregulation? ....................................... 149 Specific Discounts ........................................ 149 Deviation from Bureau Tariffs ............................. 150 Relationship of Revenues to Costs ......................... 150 Change in Price Level ..................................... 151 To What Extent is Carrier Pricing Behavior Characterized by the Use of Cross Subsidies? ............................ 151 Does Carrier Managememt See This as Constituting a Change Since Deregulation? ....................................... 151 vii VI. Supplementary Findings: Nature of Cross Subsidy .......... 152 To What Extent Has Carrier Pricing Behavior Been Characterized by Innovation ............................... 153 Does Carrier Management See This as Constituting a Change Since Deregulation? ....................................... 154 Taxonomy Development ...................................... 156 The Stigler Perspective ................................... 156 Conclusions ............................................... 157 DETAILED ANALYSIS OF DATA AND RESULTS ...................... 162 Introduction .............................................. 162 Analysis of Data and Result: Research Question 1A ........ 162 Summary: Extent of Use, Contracts vs. Tariffs ............ 164 Analysis of Data and Result: Research Question 18 ........ 164 Contracts ................................................. 165 Special Tariffs or Special Items .......................... 166 Independently Published Tariff Schedules .................. 166 Bureau Tariffs ............................................ 167 Analysis of Data and Result, Research Question 2A ......... 169 Discounting Interpreted as Specific Discounts ............. 169 Price Cutting: Deviation from Bureau Tariffs ............. 169 Examination of Group A .................................... 172 Examination of Group B .................................... 172 Examination of Group C .................................... 172 Examination of Group D .................................... 173 Examination of Group E ............................ ‘ ........ 173 Examination of Group F .................................... 175 Summary: Price Cutting, Deviation from Bureau Tariffs .... 175 Price Cutting, Relationship of Revenues to Costs .......... 177 Analysis of Data and Result; Research Question 28 ......... 180 28: Change; Discounting as Specific Discounts ............ 181 28: Change; Discounting as Price Cutting; Deviation from Bureau Tariffs ............................................ 181 Examination of Groups A-F ................................. 181 Summary of Change: Discounting as Price Cutting; Deviation from Bureau Tariffs ............................. 188 28: Change; Discounting as Price Cutting: Relationship of Revenues to Costs ...................................... 188 Summary of Change: Discounting as Price Cutting: Relationship of Revenues to Costs ......................... 191 28: Change in Price Level; Where Price Cutting is Seen as Either Specific Discounts or Price Reduction ........... 191 Summary ................................................... 191 Data Analysis and Result: Research Question 3A ........... 192 Summary; Extent of Cross Subsidy .......................... 192 Data Analysis and Result, Research Question 38 ............ 192 Summary; Change in the Extent of Cross Subsidy ............ 193 Nature of Cross Subsidy and Change in the Nature of Cross Subsidy ............................................. 194 viii VII. APPENDIX ‘n m DOW) o o o o o a Data Analysis and Result: Research Question 4A ........... 194 Data Analysis and Result: Research Question 48 ........... 197 Data Analysis and Result; Taxonomy Development ............ 197 Predators ................................................. 205 Summary: The Candidate Prcing Type "Predator“ ............ 206 Price Leaders ............................................. 207 Summary: The Candidate Pricing Type "Price Leader“ ....... 208 Cherry Pickers or Shipment Targeter ....................... 208 Summary: The Candidate Pricing Type Shipment Targeter .... 209 Strategic Business Units or S.B.U.s ....................... 210 Summary: The Candidate Pricing Type “S.B.U.“ ............. 211 Cream Skimmers ............................................ 212 Summary: The Candidate Pricing Type “Cream Skimmer" ...... 213 Premium Vendors ........................................... 213 Resisters ................................................. 214 Summary: The Candidate Pricing Type "Resister“ ........... 215 Price Aggressor ........................................... 216 Summary: The Candidate Pricing Type “Price Aggressor" .... 217 Other Taxonomic Perspectives .............................. 217 Change in Tariff and Contract Behavior .................... 218 Relationships Between Tariff Behavior and Discounting Behaviors ................................................. 218 Relationships Between Aspects of Rate Behavior and the Firm's Size and Profitability ............................. 219 Summary: Pricing Taxonomy Development .................... 219 The Stigler Perspective ................................... 220 Results in The Context of the Stigler Perspective ......... 220 Summary: The Stigler Perspective ......................... 224 IMPLICATIONS .............................................. 226 Introduction .............................................. 226 Implications to Theory .................................... 226 Implications to Practice .................................. 228 Implications to National Policy ........................... 230 Speculative Discussion .................................... 233 Overview .................................................. 234 Implications to Further Research .......................... 236 Questionnaire ............................................. 241 Letter of Introduction .................................... 245 Follow-up Letter .......................................... 247 Detailed Breakdown of Responses to Item 35-E “Other“ Rate Categories ........................................... 249 -Listing of Detailed Cross Tabulation Results Available by Special Request ........................................ 258 Statistically Significant Differences Between Candidate Pricing Type Resister and Non-Resisters [°< = .05] ....... 260 ix G. Change in Contract and Tariff Behavior Cross-Tabulated by All Other Responses Statistically Significant Results [o< = .05] ....................................... 266 H. Aspects of Rate Behavior Cross-Tabulated by the Firms Size and Profitability [o< = .05 for Statistically Significant Differences] .................................. 341 BIBLIOGRAPHY ...................................................... 344 List of Figures Page FIGURE 2- 1 Major Provisions of the Motor Carrier Act of 1980 ........... 50 3- 1 Issues in Regulatory Economics .............................. 73 3- 2 Chicago School Positions .................................... 75 3- 3 Various Viewpoints on the Extent to Which Regulation is Desirable ................................................... 100 4- 1 Mailings, Responses, and Response Rates ..................... 124 4- 2 Frequency of Carriers in Revenue Categories ................. 130 4- 3 Identification of Groups Using Rate Categories as Price Cutting Mechanisms . ......................................... 133 4- 4 Questions Regarding the Nature of Cross Subsidy ............. 138 4- 5 Pricing Taxonomy Questions .................................. 140 4- 6 Data Pattern Supporting the Stigler Perspective ............. 142 5- 1 Carrier Operating Ratios .................................... 158 5- 2 New Firms Since Deregulation as Reported by Carrier Management .................................................. 160 6- 1 Frequency of Carriers in Revenue Categories ................. 162 6- 2 Contracts Legally Defined Compared to Tariffs Legally Defined ..................................................... 163 6- 3 Contracts Economically Defined Compared to Tariffs .......... 164 6- 4 Contracts as Change ......................................... 165 6- 5 Change: Special Tariffs or Special Items ................... 166 6- 6 Change: Independently Published Tariff Schedules ........... 167 6- 7 Change: Bureau Tariffs ..................................... 168 6- 8 Carriers Engaging in Specific Named Discounts ............... 170 xi 6-10 6-11 6-12 6-13 6-14 6-15 6-16 6-17 6-18 6-19 6-20 6-21 6-22 6-23 6-24 6-25 6-26 6-27 Identification of Groups Using Rate Categories as Price Cutting Mechanisms .......................................... 172 Percentage of Revenue from Contracts, Group A ............... 173 Percentage of Revenue from Contracts, Group B ............... 174 Percentage of Revenue from Special Tariffs and Items, Group C ..................................................... 174 Percentage of Revenue from Special Tariffs and Items, Group D ..................................................... 175 Percentage of Revenue from Schedules of Independent Tariffs, Group E ..................................................... 176 Percentage of Revenue from Schedules of Independent Tariffs, Group F ..................................................... 176 Deviation from Bureau Tariffs ............................... 178 Carriers in Revenue Categories: Percentage of Traffic Measured by S Revenue Which is "Extremely Close" to Costs ...179 Carriers in Revenue Categories: Percentage of Traffic Measured by 5 Revenue on Which the Carriers are Actually Losing Money ................................................ 180 Carriers Reporting Change with Respect to Specific Named Discounts ................................................... 182 Carriers Reporting Change with Respect to Specific Named Discounts ................................................... 184 Identification of Groups Using Rate Categories as Price Cutting Mechanisms .......................................... 186 Rate Categories as Change ................................... 186 Rate Categories as Change: Subgroups Compared to the Group as a Whole .................................................. 189 Change in the Relationship of Prices to Costs ............... 190 Price Level compared with One Year Ago ...................... 191 Extent of Cross Subsidy ..................................... 193 Extent of Cross Subsidy as Change ........................... 193 xii ,)\ 6-28 6-29 6-30 6-31 6-32 6-33 6-34 6-35 6-36 6-37 6-39 6-40 6-41 6-42 6-43 6-44 6-45 Nature of Cross Subsidy and Change in Nature of Cross Subsidy ..................................................... 195 Carriers Engaging in Specific Named Innovations ............. 198 Carriers Reporting Change with Respect to Specific Named Innovations ................................................. 201 Carriers Reporting Change with Respect to Specific Named Innovations ................................................. 203 Identification of Predators and Non-Predators ............... 205 Identification of Price Leaders ............................. 207 Identification of Shipment Targeters ........................ 209 Identification of S.B.U.s ................................... 211 Identification of Cream Skimmers ............................ 212 Identification of Resisters ................................. 215 Identification of Price Aggressors .......................... 217 Data Pattern Supporting the Stigler Perspective ............. 220 Pre-deregulation Political Behavior ......................... 221 Post-deregulation Political Behavior ........................ 221 Pre-deregulation Carrier Feelings ........................... 222 Post-deregulation Carrier Feelings .......................... 222 Profitability Before and After Deregulation ................. 223 Cross-tabulation Of Political Activity by Level of Profit ...225 xiii CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION Problem and General Approach Among the major industrial nations of the world, the United States has historically placed a relatively large degree of reliance upon markets, and, therefore, upon marketing activities, as a means of resource allocation. The appropriateness of this reliance, when the resource allocations in question are those of the transportation industries, has been the subject of considerable debate and experi- mentation. Are these industries so Structured as to provide a satis- factory social result when the firms are allowed their market freedom, or should some components of these industries be considered entities which must be extensively regulated by the government? In the case of the motor carrier industry, Opinion concerning this question remains divergent. Over the course of the industry's develop- Inent, U.S. policy has varied. In 1935, it moved in the direction of extensive regulation; and most recently, it has moved in the direction of substantially greater market freedom. The Motor Carrier Act of 1980 substantially deregulated the U.S. motor carrier industry. The results of substantial policy change such as that embodied in the Motor Carrier Act of 1980, cannot be known in advance with cer- tainty. Many writers have taken the position that these markets are essentially competitive in nature and that less regulation would, therefore, result in improved performance.1'8 Others have disputed this evaluation of the Situation, some taking the position that certain components of the industry deviated too substantially from the compet- itive model to react to deregulation competitively.9»10 Others have cited or developed empirical evidence of price increases in a deregu- lation scenario,11»12 or have emphasized the possibility of price instability,13 (rate "chaos“), or damage to existing carriers.14 Beyond this discussion, there are questions as to which theoretical position provides a most appropriate perspective for analysis of the situation. While there is general agreement as to the applicability of micro economic price or industrial organization theory, there is some divergence of opinion as to which of several views provides the better' explanation of the causes and effects of economic regulation. The public interest theory of regulation (regulation protects the public from monopoly behavior) has provided an influential perspective in transportation policy.15 But other perspectives, notably those of Stigler, who suggests that regulation may, in fact, be instituted and maintained for the benefit of the regulated firms,16 and Posner who notes that the internal cross subsidy implicit in many regulatory situations may be a useful form of taxation,17 provide alternative or complementary theoretical structures. These and other such positions provide an opportunity to view the results of the 1980 deregulation in their context. An empirical investigation of pricing might determine whether prices have in fact declined, as anticipated by the competitive model and as predicted by many; or whether prices have risen, as the research findings of Chow might suggest.18 Such research might also investigate the extent to which pricing has become individualized, as might be deduced from marketing theory,19 and as suggested by Mossman and Maiers.20 Innovative behavior should also be studied, as some authors have associated regulation with the inhibition of innovation.21 Cross subsidy might be examined in the-context of arguments related to Posner's position,22 and reported behaviors might be compared with Stigler's expectations. Finally, the study might focus upon that segment of the industry for which the applicability of the competitive model has been questioned.23 This research adopts these perspectives. It is not the first reporting of results following the motor carrier act. But, earlier results should be considered preliminary, as suggested by their authors.24 Further research should be conducted as the effects of deregulation have had time to evolve, and as there is an Opportunity to separate them from the effects of the economic recession of 1980-1982. This study addresses the question of empirical results of the deregulation. It focuses upon pricing as pricing is the nexus of the market exchange. It also focuses upon pricing because many of the predictions made concerning the results of deregulation have been based upon applications of price theory. Regular route common carriers of general commodities are motor carriers which operate between fixed terminal points, carrying general freight. The study focuses upon these carriers as these are firms for which the applicability'of the com- petitive model has been questioned.25n26 These are trucking firms with heavy terminal investments and significant LTL traffic. These are the firms which may react to the deregulation with increasing concentration and which, therefore, demonstrate a potential for price behavior deviating from the competitive model. The study provides an empirical description of the current pricing behavior of these firms in the context of specific predictions made concerning motor carrier pricing behavior. Purpose and Research Questions The purpose of the study is to address the following general questions: 1. What is the current (Fall, 1983) pricing behavior of class I and Class 11 regular route common carriers of general commodi- ties? How has this behavior changed since deregulation? Is it possible to develop a taxonomy (classification) of such pricing behavior? In order to address these general questions, specific research questions were selected which comprised expectations of pricing behavior results of the deregulation, and which were also recent, researchable, and applicable to regular route common carriers of general commodities. The resulting research questions are straightforward derivations from motor carrier pricing trends identified by Temple, Barker, and Sloane in a 1982 special report for the National Council of Physical Distribution Management.27 1A. 13. 2A. 28. RESEARCH QUESTIONS To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by the use of contracts vs. tariffs (currently, Fall 1983)? Does carrier top management see this as constituting a change since deregulation? To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by extensive discounting? Does carrier top management see this as constituting a change since deregulation? 3A. To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by the use of cross subsidies? 38. Does carrier top management see this as constituting a change since deregulation? 4A. To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by innovation? (innovative price/service combinations) 48. Does carrier top management see this as constituting a change since deregulation? These research questions serve to focus the first two general questions of the study (what is the current pricing behavior and does that constitute a change since deregulation). The questions may also be seen in the context of important theoretical and empirical arguments. The first questions (1A and 18) recognize the new rate-making freedoms in the context of the essential heterogeneity of the motor carrier industry and of the shippers which they serve.28 Harper has recognized heterogeneity as an important problem when applying micro economic theory to transportation markets.29 According to some marketing writers, this heterOQeneity would require individualistic "matching" of supply with demand.30 Mossman and Maiers have noted that there is more opportunity for individual negotiation between shippers and carriers as a result of motor carrier deregulation;31 and have suggested that, in a deregulated environment, carriers are providing a more creative, individually priced service.32 A bureau tariff structure, even one of the complexity that had evolved in the U.S., would be unlikely to provide a sufficient number of Options to accomodate this need for variety when the market matching process is subjected to competitive pressure. Temple, Barker, and Sloane observed that, in some cases, shippers were interested in an expanded use of contract rates even within the LTL business.33 Their study made a move away from tariffs toward contracts a motor carrier Strategy planning assumption for the 1980's.34 The research examines both contracts per se and independent tariff making behavior which often serves many of the functions of contracting.35 The second questions (2A and 28) recognize the competitive assump- tion in terms of price reduction behavior. Many of those making predictions prior to the deregulation expected greater entry and reduced prices,36 while some disagreed.37 Substantial new entry in motor carrier markets has been documented.38 Price reductions have been documented, but documented in the context of recession.39 What will occur among regular route common carriers of general commodities as demand for their services expands with a resurgent economy? Will their price behavior be competitive, with new entry responding to the accrual of any economic profit? Or, will their relatively high barriers a) entry prevent this? The longer term effects in a segment of the industry where concentration might be expected have not yet been fully documented. The research examines both discounting interpreted as specific discounts and discounting interpreted as price reductions. The third questions (3A and 3B) reCOgnize the effect of the competitive assumption upon the welfare goals of the earlier tariff structure. Prior to the deregulation, carriers were expected to transport some types of shipments (notably rural shipments and small LTL shipments) at rates which did not meet their costs. There has been some evidence that carriers would not, in fact, have actually provided this service despite the tariff structure.40 But those carriers that did actually provide service in accordance with that structure would have cross subsidized the losing shipments. A substantial argument prior to deregulation was that this cross subsidization was desirable and that deregulation would eliminate it.41 The competitive assumption would be that such cross subsidy would not be possible to sustain, as any shipments carried at rates so substantially above costs as to allow cross subsidization of other shipments would logically be taken by competitors. 'The fourth questions (4A and 4B) address the expected effects of a change in market structure upon the innovative propensity of an indus- try. As the industry begins to behave more in accordance with the competitive model, prices can be expected to be driven to costs. l=irms may then elect to escape the effects of competition by differentiating their offerings or innovating. Thus: ...expectations of achieving a monopoly with accompanying supranormal profits through successful invention and innovation may induce firms to invest in creating new products and processes42 An alternative perspective suggests that the possession of monopoly power "might provide conditions that make business managers more willing and able to undertake the burdens of innovation.”3 Scherer suggests that what is needed for rapid technical progress is a: subtle blend of competition and monopoly with more emphasis in general on the former than the latter. and importantly: Likewise it seems important that barriers to new entry be kept at modest levels and that established industry members be exposed continually to the threat of entry by technically audacious newcomers. The research examines an industrial situation wherein the balance may have shifted toward more competition and wherein some entry barriers have been lowered. The development of a taxonomy of pricing behaviors provides a first step in the scientific investigation of marketing in this particular industry, now that the industry has been given the freedom to develop true marketing strategies. The research examines pricing behavior and attempts to classify firms according to pricing behavior. Finally, the research will examine whether or not motor carrier pricing behavior and motor carrier executive attitudes and behaviors conform with the expectations of the Stigler Theory of economic regulation. The Stigler Theory would expect that the regulation had benefited the industry. Findings that the firms were opposed to the deregulation, both before and after its institution, would support the Stigler framework. Findings that they supported active political resistance to the leg- islation would also support the perspective, as would findings that they were more profitable prior to deregulation. Methodology This study was comprised of several steps. The first step involved an extensive literature review to identify research questions. The second step involved a reexamination of the literature in order to identify observations or predictions which could be viewed as supportive of one of the research questions. For example, Harper had identified several specific innovations and specific forms of discounting in-the industry.46 These observations or predictions, together with open-ended questions, were then incorporated into an interview guide which was used in the third step. The third step consisted of exploratory interviews withlaifilot sample of carrier management, industry observers, and transportation/- physical distribution management. Individuals were selected based upon an interest in and an ability to observe motor carrier pricing activi- ties. These interviews were undertaken during June, 1983, and varied in format from a five-hour one-on-one personal interview to a two-hour telephone interview. In all cases, the interview guide was followed to the maximumextent allowable by the participants“ time, interest, and knowledge. A total of ten pilot interviews were completed. During this third phase of the research, the research questions, as narrowed and focused during the second phase, were further narrowed, focused, and translated into specific industry terms and activities. At this point, certain pricing behavior patterns which had not been anticipated in the literature were discovered, and potential classifications for the development of a pricing taxonomy were identified. The fourth step in the research consisted of a mail survey of presidents of Class I and II regular route common carriers of general commodities. The purpose of this component was to quantify the im- pressions gained during the earlier phases in the context of the research questions, as well as to pick up characteristics and behavior in support of taxonomy development and the Stigler Theory of economic regulation. Questions were developed in true, false, multiple choice, and open-ended formats. The questionnaire was developed and pretested using a convenience sample of carrier top management. Nine questionnaires were pretested in one-on-one situations, and an additional ten were mailed to a random sample of carrier presidents derived from the American Trucking Associ- ation‘s roster of regular route common carriers of general commodities. Following pretest corrections, the questionnaire was translated into a self-scoring computer readable brochure style questionnaire and mailed. 10 The questionnaire was mailed to a census of 732 Class I and Class II regular route common carriers of general commodities. The census listing was developed using the American Trucking Association's carrier file list accessed on July 22, 1983. This file list is used by the ATA to develop the American Trucking Association's Executive and Ownership Report Class I and II Motor-Carriers of Property. Accessing the file directly provided a more recent and complete listing than use of the ownership report itself. The initial mailing was accomplished on November 7, 1983, with a follow-up mailing on November 28, 1983. Upon receipt of the responses, a Statistical Package for the Social Sciences (SPSS) data file was established to facilitate the fifth step in the research. The fifth step of the research consisted of data analysis using the SPSS statistical package augmented by manual calculations. The extent to which carrier pricing behavior was characterized by the use of contracts versus tariffs was approached by asking presidents of carrier firms to estimate the percent of their firm's revenue falling into those cate- gories. Executives were asked if this estimated level constituted a change since deregulation, and statistical inference was used to determine whether or not the response pattern of the respondent group was likely to be indicative of a change on the part of the entire population. The question of discounting interpreted as the use of specific discounts was approached by identifying specific discounts and asking presidents of carrier firms whether their firms had started or stopped this behavior, engaged in more, less, or the same amount of it since deregulation, or had never engaged in the behavior. Change was inferred 11 from these data. Open-ended questions were also included. Discounting interpreted as price cutting was examined by asking carrier presidents about the extent to which the particular rate categories examined were used to offer prices below the bureau tariff that would ordinarily apply to the traffic, and by asking about the relationship of rates to costs. These questions were followed by questions concerning change in these areas. Appropriate statistical procedures were used to estimate the population characteristics from the characteristics of the respondent group. Extent and nature of cross subsidy were examined by asking for executive estimates of the percentage of their traffic (5 revenue) which was not profitable, and by asking specific questions concerning the nature of cross subsidy. Questions concerning change were also asked. Innovation was approached in the same manner as specific discounts, asking executives about specific industry innovation, deriving change from the format used and using open-ended questions. Taxonomy development, the question of whether or not pricing "types" can be identified and characterized, was approached using extensive cross tabulation. Candidate pricing types, derived from the exploratory interviews, were identified using specific questions. These questions were then used to cross tabulate all other responses. Appropriate statistical tests were applied to determine whether or not the candidate types differed from those not belonging to the “type“ along the other dimensions included in the survey. The Stigler perspective was approached by asking carrier presidents how they felt about deregulation, whether they had supported efforts to stop deregulation prior to its passage, whether they now support efforts to slow or roll back deregulation, and whether they were more profitable 12 before or after deregulation. These data were examined to determine whether they conformed with the idea that regulation is sought by a group of firms for their own protection. The research methodology is discussed in greater detail in chapter four. Limitations of the Study Some limitations of the study are inherent in the area of study selected. The research can only provide a very limited evaluation of theoretically-based predictions for several reasons. First, there is the inability to compare the results of the change in regulatory environment with parallel results for a control group. The research compares post change pricing behavior with both pre-change pricing behavicn~ and predictions of post change pricing behavior. Secondly, as a function of the inability to provide a control group, the research iS unable to separate pricing effects of the deregulation from pricing effects of the economic climate. However, comparison of this research with the research of others conducted before the nation had begun to recover from the 1980-82 recession, can begin to correct for this deficiency. Third, the predictions being tested are based upon both theoretical assumptions and empirical assumptions. For example, there is disagreement as to just how much competition is desirable in order to stimulate innovation.47 This ambiguity is confounded with the argument as to whether the particular type of carrier under study here possesses an institutional structure sufficiently close to the competitive model to allow a competitive result when deregulated.48 Despite these problems, specific predictions have been made, and evaluation of their accuracy is an important contribution. The timing of this research may 13 be late enough to allow measurement in a non-recession environment, but it may be too early to evaluate the results of concentration. This should argue for a replication of this study. Some of the limitations of the study are methodological. Despite the large number of trucking firms in the United States, the number of regular route common carriers of general commodities is relatively small. The ATA listing utilized provided a 742 firm census of this type of carrier in the Class I and Class 11 size groupings. This constraint, when coupled with the expectation of a limited respondent group, prevented the research from utilizing statistical techniques which required large respondent groups for taxonomy development. The meth- odology also assumed an ability and a willingness on the part of trucking company presidents to provide an accurate report of their firms' pricing behavior. Pretest interviews with presidents of those firms indicated that this assumption was warranted. The executives had little difficulty in recalling pre-deregulation behavior and estimating revenue percentages as required by the questionnaire. When queried about the confidential nature of pricing information, presidents responded to the effect that it was an “open“ industry and that they were used to reporting this kind of information. Contribution of the Study to Marketing The study provides an empirical examination of specific pricing behavior in considerable depth. This will provide a. contribution to knowledge and an understanding of one of the major components of the marketing mix. The study also provides a comparison of specific pricing 14 behaviors with expectations associated with deregulation. These expectations have been based upon differing combinations of empirical and theoretical knowledge and assumption. A comparison of specific results with these expectations will serve to provide or withdraw support for the combinations of empirical and theoretical assumption which lend to the prediction. For example, a finding of substantial price reduction behavior might support the argument that these carriers are behaving in accord with the competitive theoretical model. Alter- natively, one might make the empirical assumption that barriers to entry are "high enough" and that entry has "not been sufficient” for the Injcing behavior to be explained in this fashion. The same pricing behavior might then be seen as simply a manifestation of a breakdown in Oligopoly price discipline due to recession. Thus, the study does not isolate all that is required to provide a definitive judgment in these areas. It does provide a clean description of what has been the focal point Of many theoretically and empirically based arguments; post deregulation pricing behavior. Finally, the study will develop a taxonomy or classification of the pricing behaviors which have occurred in an industry where there was little previous market pricing precedent. From the standpoint of the marketing practitioner in the motor carrier industry, the study will provide insights into the relationship of specific pricing behaviors and price service combinations to finan- cial success in the reregulated motor carrier industry. Organization The remainder of this study is divided into the following chapters: Chapter II discusses the historical development of regulation in the motor carrier industry and the subsequent development of a rationale for deregulation. 15 Chapter III presents evidence and perspectives used in the debate over deregulation to understand and make predictions concerning motor carrier pricing behavior. The chapter reviews literature concerning positions on deregulation, the application of a marketing perspective to motor carriers, predictions of rate results of deregulathuu motor carrier economies of scale, and the initial results of deregulation. Chapter IV explains the methodology used in the study. It presents the research instrument, sample and sampling methods, and analytical procedures. Chapter V summarizes the major findings of the study in the context of the research questions, taxonomy development, and the Stigler Theory. Chapter VI details the analysis of data and its results. Chapter VII discusses the implications of the study's findings. hnplications to theory, practice, national policy, and further research are considered. The appendixes include copies of the cover letter, the question- naire, the follow-up letter, and supporting data. 16 Footnotes 1 Charles L. Dearing and Wilfred Owen, National Transportation Policy (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1949). 2 John R. Meyer, Merton J. Peck, John Stenason and Charles Zwick, The Economics of Competition in the Transportation Industries (Cam- bridge, MaSS.: Harvard UniverSTty Press, 1964). 3 Merton J. Peck, “Competitive Policy for Transportationr'in Perspectives in Anti-Trust Policy, ed. Almarin Phillips.(Princeton, NTJL: Princeton University Press, 1965). 4 James C. Nelson, "The Effects of Entry Control in Surface Transport,“ Transportation Economics a Conference of the Universities, ed. National Bureau Committee for’Economic ResearCh (New York: Columbia University Press, 1965). 5 lTuMnas Gale Moore, "Deregulating Surface Freight Transportati- on," in Promoting Competition in Regulated Markets, ed. Almarin Phillips (Washington, D.C.: TThe’BrOORTNgs Institution, 1975). 5 John W. Snow, “The Problems of Motor Carrier Regulation and The Ford Administration's Proposal for Reform,“ in Regulation Of Entry and Pricing in Truck Transportation, eds. Paul W. MacAvoy and John W. Snow (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1977). 7 George W. Hilton, “The Costs to the Economy of the Interstate Commerce Commission,“ in U.S. Congress, House, Joint Economic Committee, Subcommittee on Priorities and Economy in Government, The Economics of Federal Subsidy Programs (Washington, D.C.: IL SN Government Printing Office, 1973). 3 Mark Green and Ralph Nader, "Economic Regulation vs. Competiti- on: Uncle Sam the Monopoly Man,” Yale Law Journal 82 (April 1973): 871-79. 9 John C. Spychalski, "Criticisms of Regulated Freight Transport: 00 Economists Perceptions Conform With Institutional Realities?“ Trans- portation Journal 14 (Spring 1975): 5-17. 10 0. Daryl Wyckoff, “Factors Promoting Concentration of Motor Carriers Under Deregulation," Transportation Research Forum 15 (1974): 1-6. 11 U.S. Interstate Commerce Commission, Bureau of Economics, "A Cost and Benefit Evaluation of Surface Transport Regulation“ in MacAvoy and Snow, p. 7. 12 Garland Chow, “Studies of Intrastate Trucking Regulation-A Critique,“ Transportation Journal 19 (Summer 1980): 25. 17 13 Lee J. Melton, Jr., “The Competitive Transportation System: A Myth," Transportation Journal 14 (Summer 1975): 48-55. 14 Donald V. Harper, “Discussion of Papers on 'The End of Economic Regulation?'“ Transportation Journal 15 (Spring 1976): 34-39. 15 Abuse of monopoly power by railroads began the legislative evolution which resulted in the establishment of the ICC and the granting to the ICC of the powers of entry and rate control. This evolution is detailed in Chapter 2. 15 George J. Stigler, “The Theory of Economic Regulation,“ Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2 (Spring 1971): 3-21. 17 Richard A. Posner, "Taxation By Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2 (Spring 1971): 22-50. 18 Chow. 19 Essential heterogeneity of supply and demand is a.key point differentiating a marketing perspective from the perspective embodied in many economic models. See Wroe Alderson, "The Analytical Framework for lflarketing," in Marketing Classics, 4th ed., eds. Ben M. Enis and Keith K. Cox (Boston: ATTyn and Bacon, Inc., 1981), p. 24. 20 Frank H. Mossman and Gregory S. Maiers, “Creative Adjustment to Motor Carrier Deregulation,“ MSU Business Topics 28 (Autumn 1980): p. 51. 21 Dearing and Owen, p. 192. 22 The arguments concerning the welfare of small shippers and rural shippers are related to Posner's cross subsidy discussion. These arguments are considered in Chapter 2. 23 Wyckoff identifies the general commodities carrier as belonging to a group which might react to deregulation with increasing concen- tration. Wyckoff, p. 1. 24 Donald V. Harper, “Consequences of Reform of Federal Economic Regulation of the Motor Trucking Industry,“ Transportation Journal 21 (Summer 1982): 35-38. 25 Spychalski, p. 7. 25 Wyckoff, p. 1. 27 Temple, Barker and Sloane, Inc., Transportation Strategies for the Eighties A Report Prepared Under Contract to the National Council Of PhysTCaT Distribution Management (Oakbrook, Ill.: NCPDM, 1982), p. 110. 28 Essential heterogeneity of supply and demand in the motor carrier industry is discussed in Chapter 3. 18 29 Donald V. Harper, Transportation in America, 2nd ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, Inc., 1982), p. 171. 30 Alderson. 31 Mossman and Maiers, p. 53. 32 Ibid. 33 Temple, Barker and Sloane, p. 115. 34 Ibid., p. 118. 35 Discussion with Michael Redisch, Motor Carrier Analyst at the Interstate Commerce Commission, August, 1983. 35 See for example Moore. 37 See for example Chow. 33 Temple, Barker and Sloane, pp. 108-109. 39 Harper, “Consequence of Reform...“ 40 Snow, p. 28. 41 See for example U.S. Congress, Senate, The Impact on Small Communities of Motor Carrier Regulatory Revision 95th Cong., 2nd Sess. (Washington, D.C.: LLS. Government Prihting Office, 1978), p. 128 for discussion of cross subsidy and small communities. See also, U.S. Congress, Senate, Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation, Intercity Domestic Transportation System for Passengers and Freight 95th Cong., lstTess. (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977), p. 186-87 for discussion of cross subsidy and small shipments. 42 F. M. Scherer, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Per- formance, 2nd ed. (Chicago:”Rand*McNally,‘1980), p. 424. 43 Ibid. 44 Ibid., p. 438. 45 Ibid. 45 Harper, “Consequences of Reform..." 47 Scherer, p. 424. 48 Spychalski. 19 CHAPTER II THE HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENT OF REGULATION IN THE MOTOR CARRIER INDUSTRY Regulation of a Common Carrier The regulation of the motor carrier industry entails the regulation of comnon carriers. Understanding the duties and responsibilities of the common carrier will serve to clarify the economic discussion of their regulation. Common carriage is a concept derived from English common law, and it has been carried forward to be reflected in the U.S. laws concerning motor carriers.1 Historically, comon law recognized various activities as "comnon callings;" these activities were seen as essential to community life and affected with the “public interest.“2 These activities were subject to special obligations and could be undertaken only by those who had authorization. The authorization often took the form of a grant of monopoly privilege, and public regulation often accompanied the Special obligations.3 Pegrum outlines the rationale for the early inclusion of transportation activities in this category: Undertakings connected with transportation, such as inns and wharves, were placed in this category because of the» special need for protecting the public, and because of the limitation on alternatives faced by the buyer.4 The question of the applicability of this kind of criterion to the motor carrier industry as it is currently structured constitutes a major question in the literature. But as motor carriers came under federal regulation in 1935 the legal definition of a motor common carrier was officially set forth, and large segments of the motor carrier industry in the United States were to be considered common carriers. Section 203 (a) (14) of the Motor Carrier Act of 1935 as revised in 1940 states: 20 The term “common carrier by motor vehicle" means any person which holds itself out to the general public to engage in the transportation by motor vehicle in inter- state or foreign commerce of passengers or property or any class or classes thereof for compensation, whether over regular or irregular routes... The 1935 act was to apply the common carriage philosophy to segments of the emerging motor carrier industry. The act provided for control of supply through a certification procedure and minimum as well as maximum rate regulation. In return, the carriers were required to fulfill the obligations of common carriers as construed in the twentieth century. These obligations have been summarized as including: (1) the duty of service, (2) the responsibility for safe delivery of that which is entrusted to the carrier's charge, (3) the duty to treat all cus- tomers without discrimination, and (4) the duty to charge a reasonable and only a reasonable price for the service that is performed.6 As will be shown in a later section, the Motor Carrier Act of 1935 with some modification was to constitute U.S. motor carrier policy until the administrative deregulation of the late 19705 and the passage of the Motor Carrier Act of 1980. Evolution of State Regulation The individual states initiated the regulation of motor carriers. Drawing upon court decisions related to railroads, the precedent for state regulation of private property clothed with a public interest was found in the Munn vs. Illinois case.7 The power the states used had two bases. The first was “police power.“ Supreme Court Justice Roberts characterized the nature of a state‘s police power in 1934: There can be no doubt that upon proper occasion and by appropriate measures the state may regulate a business in any of its aspects, including the prices to be charged. 21 A second source of state authority is what is termed proprietary power, which allows the states authority over the use of highways constructed at public expense.9 For various stated reasons to include protection of the highways, prevention Of excess competition, control of intermodal competition, encouragement of adequate service, and coordina- tion of transportation facilities, the states used these powers to regulate the new trucking industry.10 Regulation took the form of highway system rules, safety regulation, and economic regulation in the form of entry control, rate regulation, and service regulation. Using the Munn vs. Illinois precedent to their advantage, state governments were not unaware of the precedent in the Wabash case.11 In the Wabash case, the State of Illinois was prevented from regulating the interstate activities of a railroad. The states took the position that, in the absence of federal interstate regulation, they were empowered to provide nondiscriminatory regulation of interstate carriers.12 Two cases were to have the effect on motor carrier regulation that the Wabash case had provided in rail regulation. In Buck vs. Kuykendall (1925) the state of Washington denied Buck a certificate to operate an auto stage (bus) line between Seattle, Washington, and Portland, Oregon.13 The state took the position that the area was already adequately served, but the Supreme Court decided in favor Of Buck. The court stated in essence that Washington was not regulating the use of its own highways but regulating interstate commerce in such a way as to obstruct it.14 In Bush vs. Maloy (1925), the Bush Company had been denied permis- sion to provide interstate common carrier service in the state of Maryland. Maryland denied based on its interpretation of the overall 22 welfare and convenience of the public. The Supreme Court took the position that individual state governments did not have the power no decide which interstate carriers would be allowed to operate in their respective states.15 Federal Policy The political pressure to achieve federal motor carrier regulation was evidently not as great as the pressure to achieve rail regulation. Only one year elapsed between the Wabash case and the act to regulate commerce, while ten years elapsed between the Buck and Bush cases and the Motor Carrier Act of 1935. The period was one of argument and controversy.16 Important positions taken during this period have been summarized by Johnson: Arguments for Regulation 1. Stability of rates 2. Decrease in discrimination 3. Low rates resulted in low service quality 4. Equality (railroads were subject to control) 5. Coordination among modes 6. Existing subterfuge to gain interstate status and avoid state regulation 7. Improved financial stability for carriers 8. Effective safety regulation of drivers and vehicles 9. A federal guide for uniform state regulation Arguments Against Regulation 1. Impracticality, requirement of a large bureaucracy 2. States in a better position to regulate 3. Public benefited from low rates in interstate truckingl7 23 The Motor Carrier Act of 1935 was preceded by several attempts at federal motor carrier legislation, including one prior to the Buck and Bush precedents.18 In general, these bills proposed that the I.C.C. be given jurisdiction over interstate motor carrier activities.19 Prior to passage of the Motor Carrier Act, the Federal Coordinator of Transporta- tion published his recommendations. These recommendations are cited by Pegrum: The public interest in transportation may, then, be sumnarized as requiring at least the following: (1) a minimum of outright duplication of facilities or ser- vices, (2) a transportation system which is well orga- nized and functions in an orderly and dependable way rather than one which is unstable, uncertain and a breeder of discriminations; (3) responsibility in both the narrow and broad sense... (4) financial stability and good credit. There are some who think that the thing to do is let down the bars and allow the competitors to fight it out to the finish. This would of course require practical abandon- ment of railroad regulation, leaving redress of griev- ances to the courts. The eventual result might be a kind of coordinated system of transportation achieved through survival of the fittest, but the greater competitive strength of the railroads would be likely to distort the results. The fact is that this plan of free for all competition has never worked successfully either here or . elsewhere. It has been tried and found wanting. On the other hand a partial and incomplete system of regulation, much as we have had will not work.2 Clearly competition was not the zeitgeist of the 19305. The Federal Coordinator saw the alternatives in terms of the choice between abandonment of regulation with reliance upon anti-trust laws and subjecting all transportation agencies to the same kind of regulation which had been developed for railroads»?1 In this context S. 1629 became the Motor Carrier Act of 1935. 24 The Motor Carrier Act The Act of 1935 placed for hirevmotor carriers of passengers and property engaged in interstate and foreign commerce under the juris- diction of the I.C.C. Common carriers and contract carriers were treated differently. The provisions for common carriers as summarized by Harper, required: 1. That common carriers must obtain a certificate of public convenience and necessity from the commission before they enter the industry. That carriers must publish their rates and adhere to them. That rates must be reasonable and without unjust discrimination. That 30 days notice must be given before a rate or fare could be changed. That such proposed changes could be suspended by the I.C.C. That the comnission could prescribe the maximum, minimum or actual rates and fares to be charged. That the I.C.C. had control over the adequacy of service. That the commission had control over consolidation, mergers and security issues. That personal injury, property damage and cargo insurance must be carried.22 Provisions for contract carriers required: 1. That they'obtain permits to enter, but not certificates of public convenience and necessity as was required of common carriers. That entry requirements were to be less rigorous. That they file their minimum rates and not charge less than the minimum (the commission could prescribe only the minimum rates). That they have public liability'and property damage coverage (they were not required to carry insurance to cover cargo).23 25 Numerous categories of for hire carriage were exempted from economic regulation. These included "vehicles carrying livestock, fish, horticultural and agricultural comodities (not manufactured products thereof)“;24 “school buses, taxicabs, hotel limousines, vehicles operated by the Department of the Interior in and about national parks, vehicles used to distribute newspapers, vehicles used incidental to air transportation, vehicles within one municipality and casual occasional or incidental transportation of passengers or property....“25 Private carriers were subject to safety provisions of the act but not subject to economic regulation. The legal definition of a private carrier was thus to become critical, as many carrier operations would be created in technical conformity with the definition so as to avoid economic regulation. The 1935 act defined a private carrier in the following way: The term “private carrier of property by motor vehicle“ means any person not included in the terms “common carrier by motor vehicle"; who or which transports in interstate or foreign commerce by motor vehicle property of which such person is the owner, lessee or bailee when such transportation is for the purpose of sale, lease, rent or bailment or in the furtherance of any commercial enterprise. A special term has been applied to trucking Operations which technically conform to this clause but actually function as common or contract carriage. “Grey area" operations are exemplified by trucking operations which might purchase the goods to be transported and sell them immedi- ately after the transportation is accomplished.27 The I.C.C. has applied the "primary business test“ in this area. In this test the criterion is whether transportation or another business constitutes the primary business.28 26 Administration of the Act Pegrum has summarized the administrative interpretation of the 1935 act.29 According to Pegrum, entry controls have been utilized to limit competition. In the case of common carriers, the burden of proof has been placed on the applicant, in that one who would enter motor carriage has had to prove that the public convenience and necessity reguired the granting of the certificate. Existing carriers were to be given the privilege of handling all the traffic in the area if they could do so “efficiently, economically.“30' In the case of contract carriers, the applicant had to prove that the new permit would be "consistent with public interest."31 When viewing these applications, the comnission considered the effect on the other carriers. Contract carriers were interpreted to be carriers “under continuing contracts with one person or a limited number of persons."32 This limited number was interpreted as being eight or fewer. Entry thus constrained, the commission also adopted aggressive rate regulathnn The commission did not adapt the previous precedent of "fair return on fair value," but instead chose to examine the carriers' Operating ratios.33 That protection of the carriers has been a criterion in the assignment of minimum rates is evident in the com- mission's statement concerning a 1950 case: The important considerations here are that there is a rate war, that carriers have lost and are losing traffic because of rates that as a whole are substantially lower than necessary to yield adequate revenues, and that to regain and retain traffic they are engaging in destruc- tive competitive practices. We know of no other way of correcting this situation than by placing a floor below which rates may not go without prior approval. 27 Other Major Legislation Affecting Trucking The Transportation Act of 1940 was to make many specific amendments to the Motor Carrier Act of 1935. These amendments were largely administrative in nature; clarifying exemptions, adjusting administra- tive procedures, and extending a prohibition of dual operation as both common and contract carrier.35 Beyond this, the Transportation Act of 1940 attempted a statement of national transportation policy. The national policy was declared to be: To provide for fair and impartial regulation of all modes of transportation subject to: the provisions of the act, so administered as to recognize and preserve the inherent advantages of each; to promote safe, adequate, economical and efficient service and foster sound economic condi- tions in transportation and among the several carriers; to encourage the establishment and maintenance of reasonable charges for transportation services, without unjust discriminations, undue preferences or advantages, or unfair cn~ destructive competitive practices; to cooperate with several states and the duly authorized officials thereof; and to encourage fair wages and equitable working conditions; - all to the end of developing, coordinating and preserving a national transportation system by water, highway and rail, as well as other means, adequate to meet the needs of the commerce of the United States, of the postal service, and of the national defense. All of the provisions of this act will be administered and enforced with a view to carrying out the above declaration of policy.36 As would later become evident, when the different positions taken prior to the 1935 act would again be argued, the 1940 policy act was a perfect stage for conflicting interpretation. Indeed, even without the encumbrance of vested interest, it would be difficult to interpret the policy direction intended in a document which advocated both "preserva- tion of inherent advantage, economy...efficiency“ and, at the same time, “equity and the avoidance of destructive competitive practices." As the Motor Carrier Act of 1935 and its administrative interpre- tation adapted railroad perspectives and precedents,37 the Reed 28 Bulwinkle Act of 1948 may be seen as adopting the perspective of the. Shipping Act of 1916. The Reed Bulwinkle Act granted certain anti-trust exemptions for rate bureaus or conferences used by land common carriers. This was made subject to the authority of the I.C.C. The rate bureaus were to provide a mechanism for the coordination of through rates and joint rates and had the power to set uniform rates for member carriers. Individual carriers were to have the right to establish an independent action, although some writers believe that the mores of the industry were such that this would have been unlikely.38 In 1965, Congress passed the Grey Area Act in order to close specific loopholes in the 1935 law. This act provided: 1. Increased fines and forfeitures for illegal operations. 2. Better working relationships between the states and the I.C.C. 3. That the I.C.C. may prosecute both shippers and carriers. .4. More efficient ways of infbrming states as to which carriers were authorized to Operate in their areas. 5. The I.C.C. with power to award reparation to shippers when they had incurred injuries as a result of being charged an unreasonable and therefore an unlawful rate.39 The Grey Area Act is seen as having been effective in closing some loopholes which had allowed the Operations of illegal truckers to hurt common carrier truckers.40 The Debate The Reed Bulwinkle Act was passed in 1948. It provided alum» pletion of the kind of industrial organization selected when price and entry controls were adopted in 1935. With the passage of this act, Oligopolistic interdependence was facilitated. By 1949, the question of 29 the appropriateness of this form of industrial organization was again taken up in earnest. A lengthy debate was to precede the substantial change in motor carrier policy represented by the 1980 act. The debate will be presented by first examining arguments in favor of deregulation and then examining arguments against the idea. Empirical evidence in support of these positions is examined in chapter three. ARGUMENTS IN FAVOR OF DEREGULATION Innovation and Flexibility Within a year of the passage of the Reed Bulwinkle Act, the Brookings Institution published an extensive evaluation of national transportation policy authored by Dearing and Owen.41 In their evaluation of motor carrier policy, Dearing and Owen reviewed the commission's interpretation of the 1935 act. Among their observations were: A. That the application of restrictive standards of entry tended to protect established carriers from competition, and that there was therefore inherent in the regulatory process a tendency to _r_e_s_i_s_t_ experimentation and slow technological progress.“ (This author's underlines) 8. That the long range wisdom of applying severe limitations to the operating rights of an essentially small scale industry whose chief advantage lies in flexibility has been questioned.43 While Dearing and Owen observed difficulties stemming from the I.C.C.'s interpretation of the 1935 act and while they were generally favorable toward the use of competition, they also recognized the potential difficulties of implementing transportation competition as a 30 national policy. Dearing and Owen recognized that competition in the presence of either “private manipulation or government interference" would become “unreliable as the arbiter of economic survival."44 They thus became early advocates of systems of user fees as necessary to the equitable utilization of intermodal competition in the tranSportation industry/‘5 Other observations put forth in this study included the ideas that regulation was unable in fact to actually prevent unfairness and discrimination, that government created discrimination exists in the form of differing levels of subsidy, that division of regulatory authority made the goal of transportation economy through appropriate integration difficult, and that regulation with its judicialized procedure has been harmful to private carrier management.46 Dearing and Owen set forth several principles to encourage movement in the direction of “transport efficiency and technological progress.“ Among those principles, the following pertain most directly to this study: A. If the potential contributions of the private enterprise system are to be realized, available traffic must be allocated among competing forms of transportation in accordance with economic standards of price and service competition. This means that all rates must reflect the true economic cost of performing service. Where a portion of the transportation plant is supplied initially by government, workable competition can be maintained only if the cost of providing and maintaining such facilities is charged against the direct user rather than against the general taxpayer. 8. Initiative and responsibility for basic managerial decisions must be restored to private enterprise...47 31 An Industry Competitively Structured In 1959, the Economics Department at Harvard produced what was to be a much cited work by Meyer, Peck, Stenason, and Zwick. Entitled The Economics of Competition in the TransportationIndustries,48 the work picked up the theme presented by Dearing and Owen. Analyzing the various transportation industries in depth, Meyer et. al. made the following observations about trucking: 1. Aggregate numbers present the picture of an industry with a very low level of concentration. 2. The market must be defined by the number Of carriers operating between two geographic points. Given this perspective, a trucking transportation market may sometimes be placed in the small numbers or Oligopolistic category of market structure. 3. The present market structure is largely a consequence of I.C.C. policy. Without control of entry by the I.C.C. the trucking industry would be even more unconcentrated. 4. Excess capacity in the industry was partially due to I.C.C. regu- lation. 5. Excess service competition was resulting from current policies.49 Meyer et. al. believed that U.S. trucking policy was resulting in misallocation of resources and felt that the “burden of change" lay with the common carrier industry and its regulation, rather than in restric- tions on private and contract trucking.50 Lower Rates and Adaptability to Economic Change On April 5, 1962, President Kennedy gave a tranSportation message in which he advocated "greater reliance on the forces of competition and less reliance on the restraints of regulation."51 Kennedy's specifh: 32 proposal was that minimum rate regulation should be eliminated on bulk commodities where substantial nonregulated transportation existed.52 The Kennedy message was analysed by Peck in a paper presented at an anti- trust seminar in 1963 and later published in a collection of essays.53 Peck's approach was to review the concentration of sellers, economies of scale and relative costs of various transportation modes in the context of predictions made by Opponents of deregulation (price discrimination, rail price wars damaging to truckers, ruinous competition among rail- roads and financially weakened railroads).54 Peck's evaluation did not bear these criticisms of deregulation out. Peck took the position that the public would gain from lower rates and reduction of excess capa- city.55 He went so far as to extend the argument: IHl the arguments for deregulation for bulk and agri- cultural commodities apply also tO manufactured miscel- laneous traffic.56 He concluded that a competitive policy was not only possible but desirable in transportation, advocating a much broader deregulation than that proposed by Kennedy. Peck saw the failings of regulation as providing insights into the achievements of competition; quoting his earlier work: Thus in a very real sense, the American experience with transportation regulation stands as an eloquent though negative testimonial to the great strength of free enterprise: an ability to adapt quickgy and efficiently to change in the economic enVTronment. Lack of Economies of Scale; Failure to Match Shipper Requirements Nelson's 1965 argument in favor of a deregulation focused on entry control, which he termed the “handmaiden” of minimum rate regulation.58 Nelson identified motor carriers as the transportation mode subject to the most restrictive entry limitations.59 33 Nelson cited the potential benefits of entry control (requirement of essential service, encouragement Of adequate investment, improved service and safety, avoidance of duplicate investment, coordination of through and joint rates) and contrasted them with the problems of shippers and carriers in the regulated environment. Carriers were complaining of long drawn out commission proceedings, uncertainty of proceeding results and limited grants of authority. Shippers were complaining of inadequate and costly service.60 Nelson felt that the "effects of entry control upon market structures in the transport industries are the most vital considerations in evaluating allocative efficiency"61 and drew attention to the trend toward fewer and larger carriers in the regulated motor carrier industry.62 Nelson could not find justification for entry control in the industry economies of scale and documented specific inefficiencies created by regulation.63 Nelson believed there was potential for rate reductions should the markets be deregulated and associated rate reductions on the carriage of agricultural products with entry policy in that segment of the indus- try.64 Nelson went so far as to cite the I.C.C.'s own statement to the effect that rates would be likely to fall should deregulation occur.55 Nelson also discounted the argument that regulation resulted in improved service, noting that: 1. There was no adequate market test of the shippers' general willing- ness to pay for higher service under regulated conditions. 2. That shipper complaints did not support the argument that service standards were high. 3. That lobbying efforts by agricultural and industrial shippers in support of deregulation "suggests that regulated services are not generally regarded as worth the higher rates."55 34 Dissatisfaction with Results and a Willingness to Experiment In a later Brookings study, Friedlaender prepared a background paper entitled "The Dilemma of Freight Transport Regulation."57 The paper and a summary of the 1967 conference involving a group of industry experts was published by Brookings in 1969. Of the three viewpoints identified by Friedlaender, two were in favor of at least some deregu- lation. One group felt that regulation was working badly, incurring excessive cost, and that rate deregulation, the end of common carrier obligations, and the formation of integrated transportation companies would be desirable. This group was generally composed of economists.68 The second pro-deregulation position was characterized by Friedlaender as one of unhappiness with current regulatory policy in that it had created both static costs of resource misallocation and dynamic costs Of excess capacity and poor investment decisions.69 The majority group could not agree on changes in policy, but most of the majority group supported experiments with deregulation.70 The Costs and Feasibiligy of Regulation In 1971, the President's Advisory Council on Executive Organization reported on the activities of selected independent regulatory agencies. The Interstate Commerce Commission was included in this review. The report proposed that the I.C.C., C.A.B., and F.M.C. be abolished and their regulatory responsibilities be combined within a new transporta- tion regulatory agency.71 The I.C.C. was characterized as representing "collegial" administration of its transportation industries,72 and of failing to take into account the inherent economic advantages of one mode over others by interpreting the phrase "preserve inherent advan- tages of (regulated modes)"73 as requiring the comnission protect the 35 existence of such modes.74 The report also advocated separation of the regulation function from the promotion function, noting that the I.C.C. and the C.A.B. each held both kinds of responsibility.75 Criticism of the I.C.C. continued with the 1973 publication of a compendium of papers for the Joint Economic Committee of the Congress. Entitled "The Economics of Federal Subsidy Programs," the collection included an article by Hilton on the costs to the economy of the Interstate Commerce Commission.76 Hilton characterized the I.C.C. as administering an "incomplete cartel" of common carriers which entailed costs to the economy.77 The I.C.C.'s administration of this cartel was seen by Hilton as resulting in an underutilization of resources, misallocation of traffic among modes, incentives to avoid common carriage, and inhibition of the retirement of obsolete service.78 Hilton cited a report by Ralph Nader's study group criticizing the professional competence of political appointees within the Comnission, and undertook a review'of various economists' estimates of the cost to the economy of the cartel.79 The principle beneficiaries of the cartelization were seen as proprietors of major intercity truck lines and the International Brotherhood of Teamsters.80 Hilton concluded: The economic loss from the cartelization of the transpor- tation industry is probably the largest from the inappro- priate organization of any industry, with the possible exception of the agricultural price support program. Eventually economic losses are paid for by the consumer. Ralph Nader added a consumerist's voice to the call for deregulation. A harbinger of the political coalition which would allow passage of the 1980 act was a 1973 contribution by Green and Nader.82 They argued that the system of economic regulation lacked both comprehensive theory' and a consistent goal and that the regulatory system had undermined competition and entrenched monopoly. Green and Nader stated: 36 If the problem is over-regulation based on irrational economics, then the most effective remedy is deregu- lation. Where there would be a viable competitive market but for economic regulation, the industry should be freed from all such restraint. By this standard, trucking air and water tranSport, radio and television could return to the open market.8 In 1975 Brookings published a collection of essays which included Moore's classic and much debated estimate of the societal costs of regulation.84 Moore identified the five costs of regulation as being: 1. Costs within a single mode, or inefficiency costs such as empty backhauling in the motor carrier industry. 2. Costs to the economy of shifting from low cost to high cost modes of transportation. 3. Pricing of transportation above marginal costs and non-shipment of goods due to higher prices. 4. Distortions in non-transport sectors of the economy due to loca- tional and product price discrimination. 5. Dynamic loss caused by a reduction in incentives to innovate. Using rough estimates, Moore attempted to provide what he termed an "order of magnitude" quantification of the first three cost categories in the U.S. economy. The methodology was by Moore's own admission "Very crude,"85 but Moore was confident enough to provide an order of magnitude cost estimate of between $4 billion and $9 billion.86 Moore saw the alternatives as including the granting of more power to the I.C.C., merger of the I.C.C. with other regulatory agencies, relaxation of regulatory rules, or abolition of regulation. After discussing each in detail, Moore concluded: The available evidence supports the proposition that there are no substantial economies of scale in any of the major modes of transportation, with the possible excep- tion of pipelines, and with the same exception, a 37 substantially unregulated industry could be a major improvement over the existing situation. An investi- gation of the costs of regulation suggests that they are not only substantial but monumental. It is a matter of urgent concern that steps be taken to eliminate or reduce significantly the regulation of surface freight transpor- tation.87 Wilson agreed with Moore that economic regulation of freight transportation had been a relative failure.88 But Wilson stressed a different perspective. Wilson felt that, although economic and even social regulation of monopoly or Oligopoly could be effective or desirable, the administrative problems associated with the regulation of 20,000 firms were overwhelming.89 Wilson argued that it was mainly for this reason that some alternatives in the direction of simplification and reduction of regulation seemed "long overdue."90 Objections Discounted; Cross Subsidy, Chaos, Predation In 1977, on the eve of the administrative deregulatkuu another influential document was published. The effects of the two "hand- maidens" of economic regulation, entry and pricing control, upon the trucking industry were considered in a work edited by MacAvoy and Snow and published by the American Enterprise Institute.91 This was one of a group of such works collectively referred to as the "Ford Adminis- tration Papers on Regulatory Reform." Summarizing numerous other studies, Snow concluded that under the regulatory system then in effect, rates were "high, inflexible, irrational, discriminatory" and the whole rate structure was "needlessly complex."92 Snow treated several objections to regulatory reform. He believed that the common carrier obligation to service had not, in fact, func- tioned as an effective guarantee of service to rural communities. Snow noted that the Wyoming Public Service Comnission in a survey of rural 38 service had found that only half of the carriers authorized to provide service to the towns actually did so, and that the larger carriers appeared to be serving in truckload lots only.93 Snow summarized the situation: "Clearly certification does not confer an obligation to serve."94 Snow also discounted the rate "chaos" argument, by viewing the stability of markets which were not regulated and concluding that unsettled price conditions would be brief and mild.95 Fear of monopoly was discounted, referring to lack of economies of scale and atomistic competitive market structure.96 Predatory price cutting was also seen as unlikely because it required both 1) a predator firm with superior resources and 2) high barriers to entry in order for the predator firm to recoup losses. Snow felt the second condition was not present in the industry.97 Overseas Precedent The study of overseas regulatory policy also brought support for a deregulation. In 1977, Nelson and Whitten provided the Department of Transportation with a report entitled "Foreign Regulatory Experiments: Implication for U.S." the study evaluated regulatory results in Aus- tralia, Canada, France, Germany, Great Britain, and Japan as well as policies specific to the European Comnon Market.98 Several points in this analysis were relevant to U.S. motor carrier policy. The British, for example, had deregulated trucking in 1968.99 British shippers had experienced no degradation of service, even in rural conununities.100 The British had also experienced a shift away from "own account" or private trucking since their deregulation. Nelson and Whitten also observed an "absence of excessive competition, competitive chaos, 39 generally unprofitable operations and irresponsible operators"101 in the deregulated British environment. The authors noted, however, in what might be considered a caveat for current researchers of U.S. deregula- tion, that "in times of recession, excessive competition arises in an easy to enter business in the sense that returns are temporarily limited."102 Nelson and Whitten summarized the implications for the U.S. which they had found in the British experience. The British experience shows rather clearly that an industrial economy can have stable and profitable motor goods carriers and fully satisfactory, adequate and efficient road freight service without restrictive entgy and rate controls. This is undoubtibly the principle Tesson of earlier British liberalized regulation and of today's total deregulation...103 (this author's underlines) Lessons from such overseas studies were sumnarized by Hazard in 1977.104 Hazard believed that "Western European experience indicates that regulatory reform does not result in competitive chaos as the carriers maintain, or in competitive utopia as the advocates (of deregulation) claim."105 A Growing Consensus In 1977, Hazard took a position concerning the status of the debate on deregulation. In any event the theoretical debates between the techni- cal advocates and expert opposition in the United States have gone on too long. 'niis is the type of issue that leads itself to public choice of systems after appro- priate education on the merits and disabilities of competitive and regulated approaches. In the meantime a moratorium should be placed on extension of regulation and some experimental progress made toward regulatory reform along liberalized Western European lines. 05 Many agreed with Hazard that the debate had gone on long enough to be able to make a.decision. Administrative deregulation was beginning to occur as the I.C.C. began to reinterpret existing legislaticui, and a 40 new motor carrier act was only three years away. Official reports and documents increasingly sounded the deregulation theme. National Transportation Trends and Choices, an extensive report issued by the secretary of transportation in 1977, set forth several "planning assumptions."107 Among these was the assumption that future LTL rates would reflect the cost of shipping as a result of "administrative restructuring of motor carrier rates now underway at the I.C.C. or as a result of the various measures for regulatory reform proposed by the Department of Transportation."108 Motor carrier regulatory reform was becoming a planning assumption. Official reports delivered to the Congress in the late 19705 continued to advocate deregulation and entered into extensive dis- cussions of the possible outcomes. A report for the Committee on Comnerce, Science and Transportation, requested in the first session of the 95th Congress, overviewed the trucking industry. The report was both exhaustive and SOphisticated, noting problems with conventional economic analysis Of the industry.109 The report predicted relaxation of regulation and greater freedom of entry and ratemaking together with reductions in point to point gateway and comnodity restrictions.110 The authors predicted opposite effects of deregulation in the TL and LTL segments, with TL becoming less concentrated and LTL becoming more concentrated upon deregulation.111 A report produced for the second session of the 95th Congress contained a section on "marketing considerations."112 The authors of this report felt that "aside from cost economies, marketing considera- tions favor long haul carriers and ambiguously small short haul car- riers."113 The logic was that, in a deregulation scenario, large 41 carriers offering reliable direct service to a large number of points without interline connections would be able to achieve differential advantage in the transportation markets of large national shippers. In Inarkets provided by regional shippers, density within a region, infor- mality and custom tailored service could be expected to provide a differential advantage.114 The report concludes as a result of both its marketing and economic analysis that: The predicted impact of total deregulation of motor carriage on small communities is surprisingiysundramatic ... on balance they are DOSltlve effects... The second session of the 95th congress also produced Wiedenbaum's report, The Costs of Government Regulation of Business. Wiedenbaum attached large costs to regulation, suggesting: In the case of the traditional one industry type of government regulation (as of airlines, trucking, and railroads) a greater role should be given to the compet- itive process and to market forces.1 5 The first session of the 96th Congress produced a study of the purpose and effectiveness of regulatory agencies.117 In this report, Nelson characterized the I.C.C.: The salient feature of the Interstate Commerce Commission is not how much it does, or how much it does well or badly, but how much it does not do, does not want to do and in the last analysis cannot do for either political or economic reasons. 18 Nelson felt that, although quantitative measures of the costs of regulation were likely to be inaccurate, there were many costs that Simply did not lend themselves to measurement at all, and that any benefits accruing from deregulation should be consigned to the past.119 As Congress considered motor carrier legislation, the National Transportation Policy Study Commission published its final report.120 While the document did not go without criticism,121 it was comprehensive 42 and represented a continuation of the deregulation theme. The call for substantial deregulation was becoming consensus. ARGUMENTS AGAINST DEREGULATION The consensus was not developed without substantial and continuing opposition. These arguments are now presented. Price Discrimination Among the arguments reviewed by Peck was the price discrimination argument.122 This argument noted that one effect of deregulation would be to allow differential pricing among accounts. This could conceivably allow more powerful accounts to gain substantial competitive advantage over smaller or less powerful accounts by virtue of their ability to purchase transportation services at a price advantage. Loss of Specific Benefits Nelson identified several potential benefits of entry control. These included the requirement of eSsential service, encouragement of adequate investment, improved service and safety, avoidance of duplicate investment, and the coordination Of through and joint rates.123 Nelson's evaluation of these benefits when weighed against the dis- advantages of regulation was such that he could not reconmend entry control as motor carrier policy. Nonetheless, such benefits continued to be part of the argument against a deregulation. The I.C.C identified the general benefits of regulation as in- cluding social goals such as national defense, economic development, distribution equity and environmental protection.124 In the specific context of the motor carrier industry, the commission identified the benefits as including industry stability; improved costs of capital, 43 service to rural areas and small business, reduced inventory holding costs for shippers, and the carriage of marginally profitable traf- fic.125 Rate Chaos Friedlaender's 1969 study illuminated Specific positions held by interested groups.126 A group composed largely of representatives of industry and the I.C.C. felt that major changes in the rate structure would lead to "chaotic" adjustments.127 The implication was that price adjustments in a freer market environment would be frequent and substan- tial, hindering the planning process of those relying upon common carrier services. This argument is summarized by a statement made in the 1961 report of the Specific Studies Group on National Transportation Policy for the Senate comnittee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce (the Doyle Report). . It has been found to be in the public interest a degree of stability and uniformity be introduced in the rate structure of the several modes.128 The Doyle Report suggested that policy not allow unregulated transportation to destroy or seriously compromise the effectiveness of regulated transportation, and suggested two alternatives: 1. Prohibit unregulated for hire transportation and enforce it. 2. Permit regulated transportation to so maximize its efficiency that there is less advantage to the unregulated carrier.129 This concern for stability was echoed by Melton, who termed the competitive transportation system a "myth."130 Melton pointed to the historical reasons for the development of regulation. He saw those reasons as being monopoly in the case of railroads and lack of stability in the case of the motor carrier industry.131 Melton felt that the same conditions would again obtain should regulation be abandoned.132 44 Damage to Existing Carriers Damage to the established infrastructure of carriers as the result of a more competitive industry was addressed by Harper.133 Harper believed that eased entry control would be very harmful to the existing motor carriers and that, if freedom of ratemaking were extended across modes, the big gainers would be the railroad industry, as they would be able to cut rates considerably while still retaining some contribution to fixed expenses.134 Non-Competitive Effects Several believed that a deregulation would not necessarily result in competitive behavior. One problem was in the application of existing or modified anti-trust laws. Harbeson argued that while the Sherman Act would be applicable, the price discrimination section of the Clayton Act, as amended by the Robinson Patman Act would also apply.135 Pointing out that the Robinson Patman Act was "...introduced into Congress only two weeks after the demise of the National Industrial Recovery Act, and carried forth the philosophy of the later measure regarding the desirability of restricting competition."136 Harbeson raised doubts as to whether the desired competitive objective would be achieved.137 Spychalski questioned whether segments of the industry conformed adequately to important assumptions in the competitive model.138 He concentrated on the differences between what he felt economists' perceptions were concerning the motor carrier industry and what he felt the institutional realities were. Spychalski identified the key premises underlying the economists' arguments for deregulation as being: 1. Relative ease of entry and exit. 2. Absence of economies of scale. 45 3. Inability of any one firm to significantly influence or "administer" price. 4. A homogeneous product, or at least the existence of similarities sufficient to maintain high cross-elasticity of demand. 5. Low or insignificant indivisible costs. 6. Absence Of significant externalities the benefits and costs of which cannot be internalized or assimilated into the market prices of the inputs.139 Examining the industry with these points of reference. Spychalski advanced the opinion that the output of the industry was not homogeneous in terms of the types of services provided.140 Larger carriers commanded an advantage according to Spychalski, because of their capabilities in such areas as insurance, ability to raise capital, traffic solicitation, investment in breakbulk facilities for LTL operations, and computer and information capabilities useful in carrier decision making and shipper logistics decisions.“1 Spychalski thus questioned the extent to which the motor carrier industry conformed to the ease of entry, absence of economies of scale, homogeneous product, and low indivisible cost assumptions. Wyckoff identified general commodities carriers as a segment of the industry which might react to a deregulation with increasing concentra- tion.142 Wyckoff believed there would be a period of adjustment and instability following a deregulation, but that the eventual degree of concentration that would occur in the truckload segment and less than truckload segments would be different.143 Wyckoff used "general commodities carriers" as surrogates for LTL carriers, recognizing some problems of Specification with that means of identifying the group. He 46 noted several advantages that would accrue tO large formally-managed carriers of general comnodities. Wyckoff differentiates "advantages of size" from the stricter economic definition of economies of scale, noting that advantages include spreading fixed costs and providing direct service to a broader network of points.144 The report for the Conmittee on Comerce, Science and TraNSporta- tion, requested in the first session of the 95th Congress, adopted a viewpoint compatible with those of Spychalski and Wyckoff. Why the large, long haul general freight carrier group enjoys greater relative profitability than other carrier groups is a question which deserves further research... profitability is not necessarily related in a simple way to scale economies as conventionally defined. Large carriers, for example, may enjoy higher profits related to number and location of authorized routes. Profit- ability reflects the overall suitability of firm size to market environment, not simply cost advantages. A Debate Sumnar y Thus, proponents of motor carrier deregulation believed that the motor carrier industry was sufficiently competitive in structure to respond to a deregulation with lower rates, increased innovation, flexibility, and adaptability to individual shipper needs. They also believed that the welfare goals of cross subsidy in the regulated tariff structure were not being met, that the costs of regulation were high, that regulation did not serve the consumer, that rate chaos and preda- tory pricing were unlikely, and that overseas precedent was favorable to deregulation. Those opposed to deregulation felt that a deregulation of the industry would result in rate chaos and price discrimination, loss of important benefits such as industry stability, high service levels, and adequate service to rural and small shippers, and would also result in 47 damage to the established carrier infrastructure. Strong arguments were also made to the effect that all segments of the industry would not, in fact, respond competitively. LTL carriers, operationalized as carriers of general commodities with substantial terminal investments, might be expected to react with increasing concentration. This research examines whether or not the pricing behavior of regular route common carriers of general commodities, the group identified by Wyckoff, Spychalski, and others as unlikely to behave competitively, is currently conforming to specific competitive expec- tations. ' Administrative Deregulation As the debate matured, and beginning in 1977, the I.C.C. began a process of administrative deregulation through interpretation of existing legislation. The commission effectively lowered barriers to entry,146 narrowed the interpretation of who may protest an application, and shifted the test of claimed injury to those protesting to the level of being "contrary to the public interest."147 Private carriers were no longer denied the opportunity to apply for common or contract carrier rights, and contract carriers were no longer rigidly held to the "rule Of eight."148 The commission made a general finding in 1978 that the holding of both common and contract authority was "consistent with the public interest"149 and began to ease their policies concerning gateways, circuitous routing, and the carriage of regulated commodities by exempt carriers.150 Additionally, the commission enlarged urban commercial zones and zones incidental to transportation by aircraft.151 By 1979, the commission had begun discussions of ratemaking flexibility' and increased attention to the spirit of anti-trust legislation.152 48 One author evaluated the commission's actions as having made regulatory reform a "fait accompli" and suggested that: Until its changes have proved their worth, and the truckers charges are demonstrably lower and their services improved, there would seem to be little ppint in the Congress ratifying the commissions experiment. 53 But, "ratify" they would. In the mid 19705 a legislative process began which was to culminate in the Motor Carrier Act of 1980. The Legislative Process Bills aimed at regulatory reform appeared as early as 1972. In November 1975, President Ford introduced the Motor Carrier Act, HR 12793. The bill included provision for liberalization of entry and removalcfligateway and route restrictions. It empowered haulers of agricultural commodities to carry regulated commodities on return trips, expanded comnercial zones, enlarged areas of operation incident to air transportation, reduced restrictions on proprietary trucking, allowed for increased pricing flexibility and limited the activities of rate bureaus.154 In early 1979, the legislative question was again put to the Congress. Senators Kennedy, Metzenbaum, Ribicoff, and Hayakawa intro- duced the "Kennedy Bill," (S. 710) to the first session of the 96th congress.155 The bill proposed to withdraw the antitrust immunity which had been afforded the rate bureaus by the Reed Bulwinkle Act. The Trucking Competition and Safety Act of 1979 included provisions to remove restrictions on contract carriers, liberalize Operations of exempt carriers, and provide greater rate freedom.”6 The next major piece of legislation proposed was H.R. 6418, which was to become the Motor Carrier Act of 1980. 49 The Motor Carrier Act of 1980 The committee report on H.R. 6418 characterized the Motor Carrier Act of 1980 as "the product of over 18 months of continuous study"157 and characterized the bill as "Offering increased Opportunithes for new carriers to get into the trucking business and for existing carriers to expand their services."158 The bill would accomplish this by modifying the public convenience and necessity test, allowing existing carriers to expand service, and by eliminating gateway and circuitous route restric- tions.159 The bill would limit the scope of collective ratemaking and give carriers the right to raise or lower rates by 10% without I.C.C. interference. The bill would also allow for negotiation of reduced transportation rates in exchange for limited liability on the trans- ported property.160 The majority of the comnittee felt that the bill would result in adequate service to small conmunities and would result in no degradation of highway safety.161 Lower rates and lower consumer prices were expected, as well as improvements in energy efficiency.162 Mhunity'views expressed by committee members included Ertel's position that the legislation did not do enough to encourage additional competition. This would mean that increased rate freedom would be most likely to result only in rate increases.163 Abdnor's minority view was that the bill would result in "price discrimination and a loss of service to small communities."164 The major provisions of the 1980 bill have been summarized and are displayed in Figure 2-1. The passage of the Motor Carrier Act of 1980 has been followed by I.C.C. interpretations which have allowed substantial market freedom for motor carriers. An effective deregulation has been realized. It now remains to evaluate evidence concerning the effects of this substantial policy change. 50 Figure 2-1 Major Provisions of the Motor Carrier Act of 1980 Easier entry provisions: Any "fit willing and able carrier" who provides a public service can enter the regulated trucking industry. Burden of proof in authority proceedings shifts from applicant to protestant. (Sic) Zone of ratemaking freedom: Carriers can raise or lower rates by 10% without I.C.C. approval. The commission may under certain circumstances increase the flexibility zone by 5%. Reduced bureau activity: Curtails rate bureau activity by prohibiting bureau inter- ference with any carriers right of independent action and by limiting rate discussions to companies actually participating in the traffic. Expanded contract carriage: The "rule of eight" shippers which had limited the number of shippers a contract carrier could serve was eliminated. The I.C.C. may not impose geographic restrictions on contract carriers and carriers can hold both common and contract operating authorities. Compensated intercorporate hauling: IS allowed where a 100% owner - subsidiary relationship exists. Removal of operating restrictions: Gateway and circuitous routing restrictions are lifted. Carriers may serve intermediate points on their authorized routes. Value based pricing: Carriers and shippers may negotiate reduced rates for reduced liability. Agricultural co-op traffic: Agricultural cooperatives may handle 25% of their total” interstate tonnage in non-member shipments. This is up fro 15%.165 51 Footnotes ‘1 Taken from Donald V. Harper,Transportation in America, 2nd ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, Inc., 1982), p 123 and James C. Johnson, Trucking Mergers a Regulatory Viewpoint (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Bboks, Inc., 1973), pf38. 2 Harper, p. 123. 3 Discussion of authorization derived from Dudley F. Pegrwn, Transportation Economics and Public Policy, 3rd ed. (Homewood, Ill.: RiChard D. Irwin, Inc., 1973), p. 103. 4 Ibid. 5 U.S., Motor Carrier Act of 1935, Sec. 203 (a) 14 as revised in 1940, as quoted‘in James C? Ubhnson, TruckingyMergers A Regulatory Viewpoint (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, Inc., 1973), p. 38. 5 Pegrum, p. 100. 7 James C. Johnson, Trucking Mergers A Regulatory Viewpoint (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, Inc., 1973), p. 23. 8 Ibid., p. 24. 9 Ibid. 10 Ibid., p. 25. 11 Ibid., p. 31. 12 Ibid. 13 Ibid. 14 Ibid., p. 32. 15 Discussion of the Buck vs. Kuykendall and Bush vs. Maloy cases taken from Johnson, pp. 23-25 and 31-32. 15 Pegrum, p. 314. 17 Johnson, pp. 33-36. 18 Ibid., p. 35. 19 Ibid. 20 Pegrum, p. 314. 21 Ibid., p. 315. 52 22 Harper, pp. 467-68. 23 Ibid. 24 Taken from Harper, pp. 467-68. 25 Johnson, p. 44. 25 U.S., Motor Carrier Act of 1935, Sec. 203 (2) (17) as cited in Johnson, p. 42. 27 Johnson, p. 42. 28 Ibid. 29 Discussion of the administrative interpretation of the 1935 Act is condensed from Pegrum, pp. 321-26. 30 Pegrum, p. 322. 31 Ibid., p. 323. 32 Ibid. 33 Ibid., p. 325. 34 "Class and Commodity Rates New York to Philadelphia, MCC 289, 298-99 (1950)" as cited in Pegrum, p. 327. 35 U.S., The Transportation Act of 1940, pp. 10-14. 35 Ibid., p. 1. 37 Pegrum, pp. 333-34. 38 Discussion of the Reed Bulwinkle Act condensed from Johnson, pp. 49-50. 39 Johnson, p. 50. 40 Ibid. 41 Charles L. Dearing and Wilfred Owen, National Transportation Policy (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1949i. 42 Ibid., p. 192. 43 Ibid. 44 Ibid., pp. 352-53. 45 Ibid., pp. 377-78. 45 Ibid., pp. 355-55, 359, 373, 378. 47 Ibid., pp. 377-78. 53 43 John R. Meyer, Merton J. Peck, John Stenason and Charles Zwick, The Economics of Competition in the Transportation Industries (Cam- bridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1964). 49 Ibid., pp. 211-13, 218-19. 50 Ibid., pp. 221-22. 51 Merton J. Peck, "Competitive Policy for Transportation?" in Perspectives in Anti-Trust Policy, ed. Almarin Phillips (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1965), p. 245. 52 Ibid., p. 245. 53 Peck. 54 Ibid., p. 254. 55 Ibid., p. 255. 55 Ibid., p. 259. 57 Meyer et. al., p. 272 53 James C. as cited in Peck, p. 272. Nelson, "The Effects of Entry Control in Surface Transport," Transportation Economics a Conference of the Universities, ed. National Bureau Cbmmittee for Economic Research (New York: Columbia University Press, 1965). 59 5O 51 52 53 54 55 55 Ibid. Ibid. Ibid. Ibid. Ibid. Ibid. Ibid. Ibid 57 Ann , p. 384. , p. 383. , p. 396. , p. 405. , pp. 405-09. , p. 414. , p. 415. ., pp. 416-17, 422. F. Friedlaender, The Dilemma of Freight Transport Regulation (Washington, D.C.: 68 Ibid., p. 185. 59 Ibid. The Brookings Institution, 1969). 54 70 Ibid., p. 187. 71 President's Advisory Council on Executive Organization, A New Regulatory Framework: Report on Selected Regulatory Agencies (Wash- ington, D.C.: U.Sl Government Printing Office, 1971), p. 61. 72 Ibid. 73 Appears in the National Transportation Policy Statement of the Transportation Act of 1940. 74 President's Advisory Council, p. 71. 75 Ibid., p. 79. 75 George W. Hilton, "The Costs to the Economy of the Interstate Conmerce Comnission," in U.S., Congress, House, Joint Economic Com- mittee, Subcommittee on Priorities and Economy in Government, Ipe Economics of Federal Subsidy Pro rams (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Govern- ment PrintTNQ Office, 1973), pp. 737-33. 77 Ibid., p. 707. 78 Ibid., pp. 709, 713-14, 717. 79 Ibid., pp. 725, 728-31. 80 Ibid., p. 731. 81 Ibid., p. 733. 32 Mark Green and Ralph Nader, "Economic Regulation vs. Compe- tition: Uncle Sam The Monopoly Man," The Yale Law Journal 82 (April 1973): 871-89. 83 Ibid., p. 883. 34 Thomas Gale Moore, "Deregulating Surface Freight Transporta- tion," in Promoting Competition in Regulated Markets, ed. Almarin Phillips (Washington, D.C.: lThe Brookings Institution, 1975). (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1975). 85 Ibid., p. 72. 86 Ibid., p. 71. 87 Ibid., p. 93. 33 George W. Wilson, "Regulation, Public Policy, and Efficient 1:595:51? 3;.Freight Transportation," Transportation Journal 15 (Fall 89 Ibid. 55 90 Ibid. 91 Paul W. MacAvoy and John W. Snow, eds., Regulation of Entry and Pricing in Truck Transportation (Washington, D.C.: American EnterpriSe Institute,*1977). 92 John W. Snow, "The Problems of Motor Carrier Regulation and the Ford Administration's Proposal for Reform," in MacAvoy and Snow, p. 8. 93 Ibid., p. 28. 94 Ibid. 95 Ibid., p. 35. 95 Ibid., p. 37. 97 Ibid., p. 38. 93 U.S., Department of Transportation, Federal Railroad Adminis- tration, Office of Policy and Program Development, James R. Nelson, ed. Foreign Regulatory Experiments: Implications for U.S.: An Analysis and Evaluation of FOreign Re ulatory Experience, Report No. FRA-OPPD-77-24, (Washington, D.C.: U.S. vernment Printing Office, 1977) 99 Ibid., p. 3-51. 100 Ibid. 101 Ibid., p. 3-53. 102 Ibid. 103 Ibid., p. 3-55. 104 John L. Hazard, "National Transportation Policy Administration (Transitional Lessons From Home and Abroad)," Transportation Journal 16 (Summer 1977): 5-19. 105 Ibid., p. 11. 106 Ibid., p. 12. 107 U.S., Department of Transportation, National Transportation Trends and Choices to the Year 2000, (Washington,_DIC.:‘_U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977), p. 176. 108 Ibid. 109 U.S., Congress, Senate, Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation, Intercity Domestic Transportation System for Passengers and Frei ht, 95th Cong., lst Sess. (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Prinfing %ffice, 1977), p. 220. 56 110 Ibid., p. 239. 111 Ibid., pp. 239-40. 112 U.S., Congress, Senate, The Impact on Small Comunities of Motor Carrier Regulatory Revision, 95th Cong., 2nd Sess. (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978). 113 Ibid., p. 109. 114 Ibid., p. 110. 115 Ibid., p. 132. 115 Murray L. Weidenbaum, The Costs of Government Regulation of Business, A study prepared for the Joifit Economic Committee of the Congress, 95th Cong., 2nd Sess. (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978), p. 25. 117 U.S., Congress, Senate, Committee on Governmentalluiairs, Framework for Re ulation, 5. Doc. No. 96-14, 96th Cong., lst Sess. (Washington, D. .: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1978). 113 James R. Nelson, "Abstract of Regulation of Overland Movement of Freight" in Framework for Regulation. 119 Ibid., p. 55. 120 National Transportation Policy Study Commission, National Transportation Policies Throu h the Year 2000 (Washington, D. .: Government Printing Office,T197 ). 121 Ernest W. Williams, Jr., "The National Transportation Policy Study Commission and Its Final Report: A Review," Transportation Journal 19 (Spring 1980): 5-18. 122 Peck, p. 254. 123 Nelson, "The Effects of Entry Control...", p. 383. 124 U.S., Interstate Commerce Comnission, Bureau of Economics, A Cost and Benefit Evaluation of Surface Transport Regulation, (Washing? ton, D.C.: 71976), p. 5. 125 Ibid., pp. 15-21. 125 Friedlaender. 127 Ibid., p. 186. 128 U.S., Congress, Senate, Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, Special Studies Group on Transportation Policies in the United States, National Transportation Policy, Report No. 445, 87th Cong., lst Sess. (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office 1961),;L 155-56. Also referred to as the "Doyle Report." 57 129 Ibid., p. 150. 130 Lee J. Melton, Jr. "The Competitive Transportation System: A Myth," Transportation Journal 14 (Summer 1975): 48-55. 131 Ibid., p. 49. 132 Ibid., p. 54. 133 Donald V. Harper, "Discussion of Papers on 'The End of Economic Regulation?'" Transportation Journal 15 (Spring 1976): p. 39. 134 Ibid. 135 Robert W. Harbeson, "Pricing Developments in Transportation and Public Utilities: Comment," Transportation Journal 14 (Spring 1975): 42-48. 136 Ibid., p. 44. 137 Ibid. 138 John C. Spychalski, "Criticisms of Regulated Freight Transport: 00 Economists' Perceptions Conform With Institutional Realities?" Trapgportation Journal 14 (Spring 1975): 5-17. 139 Ibid., p. 5. 140 Ibid., p. 7. 141 Ibid., pp. 7-8. 142 0. Daryl Wyckoff "Factors Promoting Concentration of Motor Carriers Under Deregulation" Transportation Research Forum 15 (1974): 1-6. 143 Ibid., p. 1. 144 Ibid., p. 5. 145 U.S., Congress, Senate, Intercity Domestic Transportation System..., p. 220. 145 Ex Parte NO. 55 as cited in Fritz R. Kahn, "Motor Carrier Regulatory Reform Fait Accompli," Transportation Journal 19 (Winter 1979): p. 7. 147 Kahn, p. 7. 148 Ibid., p. 8. 149 Ibid. 150 Ibid. 58 151 Ibid. 152 Ibid., p. 9. 153 Ibid., p. 10. 154 Ibid, pp. 7-9. 155 Lester M. Bridgeman "Anti-Trust Impact on Motor Carriers of the Proposed 'Kennedy Bill' Repeal of the Reed Bulwinkle Act," Transporta- tion Journal 19 (Fall 1979): p. 38. 155 Kahn, pp. 7-9. 157 U.S., Congress, House, Committee (Ml Public Works and Transportation, Re art To ether with Additional and Minority Views to Accompgny H.R. 64I§ 96th Cong., 2nd Sess. (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1980), p. 1. 158 Ibid., p. 2. 159 Ibid., p. 3. 160 Ibid., p. 4. 151 Ibid., pp. 5-6. 152 Ibid., pp. 7-8. 153 Ibid., p. 99., 164 Ibid., p. 103. 155 AS summarized by Traffic Management, January 1981, p. 56. 59 CHAPTER III THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS Introduction The debate concerning the outcomes of a substantial deregulation of the motor carrier industry has generally been informed by economic theory. The positive arguments have been based on the assumption that the industry would begin to price more in accordance with the competi- tive model. Lower rates and greater innovation might be expected. The Opposition expected that the welfare effects of cross subsidy might be lost, existing carriers would be hurt, and the natural price adjustments of the competitive marketplace might be "chaotic." In the case of the regular route comon carrier of general comnodities, the LTL group, the argument against deregulation was different. The argument was the this group showed the potential for increasing concentration upon deregula- tion. Their pricing behavior might, therefore, in the longer run, be in accordance with the expectations of Oligopoly price theory. If, in fact, pricing behavior does approximate competitive be- havior, and existing carriers are economically hurt by the deregulation, the situation may conform to the expectations of the Stigler theory of economic regulation. The carriers may have supported regulation which was in their economic interest. This chapter first reviews the theory of competition and Oligopoly, and complementary theory or issues in market regulation, marketing, strategy, and pricing. These are viewed in the context Of their application to the industry case. Empirical evidence is then con- sidered, first in the context of competitive effects, then in the context of market regulation and the application of a marketing per- 6O spective. Finally, the current study is placed in these theoretical and empirical contexts. THEORETICAL ANALYSIS Economic Models Arguments in favor of substantial deregulation of the motor carrier industry have been largely based upon the proposition that the industry' ‘was structured competitively; that barriers to entry were low, that the fixed component Of costs was small, that economies of scale were minimal to nonexistent, and that the industry showed a very low degree of concentration.1 Deregulation of such an industry could be expected to result in pricing behavior more in line with the competitive economic model than that observed prior to the deregulation. Dissenting Opinion cited problems with competitive behavior but also cited the importance of considering not the trucking industry but the specific subindustries noting that, in certain of these subindus- tries, the conformance to the competitive model was not good. Of particular interest was the LTL carrier. LTL carriers, with their relatively high investment in fixed terminal facilities, and with advantages for larger carriers deriving from the provision of service to to a broad network of points, might be expected to react to a deregu- lation with increasing concentration.2 This would result in a potential for Oligopoly pricing behavior. This approach adopts Wyckoff's use of "general commodities carriers" as a surrogate for the LTL group and examines the post deregulation pricing behavior of that group. Will this pricing behavior be more nearly competitive or more nearly oli- gopolistic? 61 The Competitive Pricing Model Extensive economic regulation is difficult to defend if the case can be made that the the market under consideration approximates the competitive model. When conditions approximate those of the competitive model, a market without economic regulation will behave with a series of adjustments such that, after adjustment, price will equal minimum average cost of production. Economic profits attract new entrants when prices exceed this minimum average cost and the resulting shift of the supply curve drives prices toward costs. Should the price be less than minimum average costs, firms exit the industry and the supply curve shifts back to the left, allowing price to move upward to the minimum average cost. In the long run economic profits for firms in competitive industries are equal to zero.3 The perfectly competitive model requires several important assumptions. These include the assumptions that each economic agent acts as a price taker, that the product is homogeneous, that there is free mobility of all resources including free entry and exit of firms, and that all economic entities in the market possess complete and perfect knowledge.4 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case If the motor carrier industry is structured competitively, entry control and minimum rate regulation are likely to be counterproductive, and a deregulation is likely to result in prices more nearly in align- ment with costs and, up to the point of extremely rigorous competition, a greater innovativeness. If a segment of the motor carrier industry has the structural attributes which would lead to Oligopoly behavior in a deregulated environment, removal of maximum price controls might not be warranted, or increased anti-trust vigilance may be required in the 62 case of that segment. These perspectives may be derived. straight- forwardly from micro economic theory. In this case, the question might be, did regulation allow a basically competitive industry to function as an Oligopoly? Or, in the case of the industry segment under consider- ation, did regulation control an Oligopoly? Application: The Appropriateness of the Competitive Model The initial conformance of the motor carrier industry with the competitive model is good. The way is publicly provided and available to all, and a tractor trailer combination is within the reach of an individual citizen. In this sense, barriers to entry must be considered to be low. The economies Of scale argument is not straightforward, but numerous studies have supported the idea that they are minimal.5 Pegrum considers the facilities and equipment not to be so highly specialized as to prevent shifting between markets or geographic areas and notes that, in general, new traffic may be found to complement the purchase Of new equipment in small increments.5 Studies have also demonstrated that the industry is an extremely high variable cost industry.7 Even maintenance of way expenses are distributed on a "use" basis which tends to be proportional to the traffic carried.8 Joint and comnon costs in the industry are considered to be small, and the potential for "ruinous" competition is seen as being low, because Of the low proportion of fixed costs.9 Pegrum summarizes the case for the applicability of the competitive model to the motor carrier industry. In other words, the cost structure of motor transport is such as to make it possible for competition to function as a fully effective force for establishing economical prices. In fact, obstacles placed in the way of such competitive pricing will redound only to the benefit of the protected carriers. It will be to the disadvantage of the consuming public and the carriers that are precluded from competing. This does not mean that there 63 is no place for the common carriers in motor transport. What it means is that the economic basis for imposing limitations on competition among common carriers is lacking. These arguments, together with the observation that the industry, when viewed in the aggregate, presents a low level of concentration,11 have constituted a strong case for the appropriateness of market competition among motor common carriers. Application: Problems With the Competitive Model Commonly used in the context of manufacturing industries, the competitive model may require substantial interpretation when placed in the motor carrier industry context. The model has Specific require- ments. Furguson and Gould have noted that the model requires that each economic agent acts as price taker, that the product is homogeneous, that there is free mobility of all resources, including free entry and exit of business firms; and that all economic agents in the market possess complete and perfect knowledge.12 In discussing the attributes of this model in the motor carrier industry context, Spychalski notes that it also requires absence of economies of scale, low or insignifi- cant indivisible costs, and absence of significant externalities, the benefits and/or costs of which cannot be "internalized" or assimilated into the market prices of the outputs which occasion them.13 Examination of a motor carrier market in this context presents some problems. Most straightforwardly, a motor carrier market exists between two points, and aggregate data concerning motor carrier numbers and concentration, even when corrected for geographic area of operation and type of commodity specialization, provide a poor approximation of carrier activity between any two points. Schary summarizes this observation. 64 The dilemna of measuring a transportation market is that there are no distinct boundaries, that any measure of a market is potentially inadequate in the long run. Ideally, freight transportation markets should be defined by origin and destination, comnodity and shipment size, but even these parameters fail to hold when the long run is considered and transportation users are free to adjust their market choices in response to conditions of cost and service. Thus, the "structure" of a motor carrier transportation market may be difficult to gauge, atomistic competitive structure in an aggregate motor carrier group may not be indicative of competitive structure in individual motor carrier markets. Spychalski noted that pro deregulation arguments ranged from the position that the market in question was at the very least "workably competitive" to "highly duplicative of the purely competitive model at best."15 He found difficulties with the homogeneity of output assumption, citing substantial differences in the types of services produced and differing shipper requirements.16 He noted, that while truckload movements of packaged or bulk commodities conform most closely to the model, LTL and TL shipments of general freight as well as LTL shipments of small packages, offer substantial advantages to larger firms.17 Thus, Spychalski found at least some segments of the industry to be in poor conformance with the competitive model. Application: Competition, Oligopoly and the General Comnodities Carrier Both Spychalski and Wyckoff have focused upon the LTL carrier of general commodities as perhaps being in poor conformance with the competitive model.18 Relatively high fixed costs for terminal facilities and advantages of’size in the form of density and scope of coverage have been cited.19 Should the Wyckoff and Spychalski perspectives be correct, one would expect general commodities carriers 65 eventually to engage in Oligopoly pricing behavior, although this may be preceded by a period of predation wherein the aggressive price cutting may be difficult to distinguish from the price dynamics anticipated by the competitive model. The eventual Oligopoly behavior should be characterized by an awareness of Oligopolistic interdependence on the part of the par- ticipants; by an acute awareness of the firms pricing in the context of other firms pricing. Efforts to discourage entry might be expected, as well as efforts to divide markets, possibly on a geographic basis. Powerful firms may be expected to exert price leadership, with the bulk of the firms following their pricing behavior within a short period of time. (kmnmn costing formulae, if only ostensibly for professional guidance, might gain broad acceptance, and bureau tariffs might be expected to be used as focal points. All of this should result in pricing which does not approximate costs as closely as would be required by the competitive model. I Complementary Theoretical Perspectives While the comparison of the economic models of Oligopoly and competition provide a primary theoretical perspective for the study, other perspectives are useful in developing a more complete picture of the motor carrier deregulation. As the industry transitions from a situation of strict regulation to one of greater market freedom, these perspectives may become relevant. In this section, selected theoretical perspectives from marketing, marketing strategy, and pricing will be reviewed. The difficulties of approximating tranSportation industry pricing behavior with conventional price theory have been discussed by Harper.20 66 In addition to the difficulties which are common to the analysis of all industries, such as the assumptions of rational decision making, availability of full information, profit maximization, and a Single product or service, Harper cited several problems peculiar to trans- portation.2l These included the heterogeneity of the industry, the differences between market structures along specific routes, and the substantial complexity of the product/service line.22 Heterogeneity If Harper's criticisms are based upon heterogeheity and complexity, the use of a theoretical perspective which proceeds from heterogeneity, rather than homogeneity, might be warranted. Alderson's analytical perspective reflects this view: An advantageous place to start for the analytical treatment of marketing is with the radical heterogeneity of markets. Heterogeneity is inherent on both the demand' and supply sides. The homogeneity which the economist assumes for certain purposes is not an antecedent condition for marketing. Insofar as it is realized, it emerges out of the marketing process itself.23 Alderson's assumption of heterogeneity as the basis for his perspective leads to several concepts useful in the analysis of the motor carrier problem. First among these is the concept of ecological niche. Differential advantage is implicit in heterogeneity, and the existence of differential advantage yields to the firm "a position in the marketplace known as 'ecological niche'."24 Also useful is the identification of the fundamental purpose of marketing in the context of essential heterogeneity of demand and supply. This purpose is to "effect exchanges by matching segments of demand with segments of supply."35 Finally, marketing itself is seen as "the exchange which takes place between consuming groups and supplying groups."26 This view 67 provides a theoretical perspective for a more individualistic firm by firm understanding of the motor carrier industry, a marketing perspec- tive. Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case The heterogeneity of demand for transportation service is derived from the heterogeneity of firms' locations, heterogeneity of raw and component material supply and heterogeneity of firms' customer service requirements. Location and material supply are straightforward, while the differences in customer service between industries has been docu- mented by LaLonde and Zinzer.27 Even within an industry, distribution requirements may differ in accordance with the firm's marketing strat- egy, as discussed by Wagenheim.28 Heterogeneity of supply is also apparent. Carriers are specialized as private or for hire, regulated or unregulated, common or contract, and within the common carrier group, specialized as to the carriage of some 17 different commodity groupings.29 Carriers costs may differ substantially, as between union and non-union Shops and carriers may elect to solicit different types of traffic within their Specific commodity groups. Carriers are specialized as local, regional, or” national and may elect to specialize in such ecological niches as overnight delivery of LTL traffic or large TL commitments. Beyond this, the trucking firms differ as to their base and mode of operation and their balance of traffic. Two trucking firms bidding the identical service package into an account may find their costs of service to be very different. One may have few incremental costs, the result of using an empty backhaul to service the account. Another may have large incremental costs of service, the result of being able to find no backhaul to balance the new service. 68 Thus, we may expect motor carrier firms in a deregulated environ- ment to find a careful matching process to be most adaptive. Price will be the nexus of the exchanges involved, but individual firms may avoid general industry pricing trends by virtue of finding individualistic ecological niches. A general trend toward more competitive pricing behavior would only have to be followed if market information were good enough to allow any increase in competition within the total industry to find the individual "niche" or point to point transportation market under consideration. Portfolio Theory A perspective from the area of corporate strategy may also serve to illuminate motor carrier pricing behavior. Boyd and Larreche have provided a consensus position concerning the definition of strategy. . Most writers on the subject agree that a firm's strategy is essentially an adaptive search process which is €3"$2§3§3522t20"31.39El”???1°C..33382222385 over “me In this context, this study may be viewed as one in strategy, involving a change in the firm's legal and competitive environments. Portfolio theory is but one of the many perspectives in marketing strategy. Several versions are extant including those of Day,31 Hall,32 Shell,33 and General Electric.34 Criticism of the mechanistic use of this perspective has been voiced, as such use might cause the firm to be distracted from the essential question of sustainable competitive advantage.35 But the portfolio perspectives remain available to corporate planners. The details of these perspectives are unimportant to this research, but their central philosophy illustrates a perspective. Conglomerate management may elect to accept substandard returns in a division which it views as a long term investment. 69 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case In the case of conglomerate investment in a common carrier of general commodities, the judgment on the part of top management might be that barriers to entry in the form of terminals for LTL service, adequate equipment for dense coverage of a regional or national network, and associated information processing might warrant treating the trucking firm as an investment. Low returns and lowered pricing may be accepted if the parent company feels that this will allow them to survive a shake out and recoup their investment later, perhaps through Oligopolistic pricing behavior. This form of conglomerate based predatory pricing may be occurring within the ranks of regular route common carriers of general commodities. Pricing Perspgctives Beyond the insights of economic price theory , several other, more specific pricing perspectives have been developed. Several of these have application to the motor carrier industry case. Price Defined Measurement of absolute price levels is likely to give little meaning outside of the imnediate cost context. Adelman has provided definitions of the "product" and the "price" in distribution. Adelman believed that, on the whole, the best concept of wholesale and retail price is value added or gross margin.35 Adelman felt that, in a distribution context, elements of monopoly would raise the margin above the competitive optimum, but that low entry requirements would generate countermovements whenever this excess builds up to some critical point.37 Increased competition, therefore, is likely to be reflected in reduced gross margins, regardless of any inflationary trend in absoluter price level. 70 Patterns of Corporate Pricing Behavior Relaxation of the economist's homogeneity assumption may have to be accompanied by relaxation of the profit maximization assumption as well. Several perspectives illustrate pricing behavior which may deviate from profit maximization. Means considered the difficulty with which corporate prices began downward movements.38 He decided that corporations must "administer prices." An administered price is set by fiat and held constant for a period of time and a series of trans- actions.39 A response appeared in 1970 when Stigler and Kindahl published The Behavior of Industrial Prices.40 Stigler and Kindahl closely examined price behavior in those industries which Means con- sidered most characterized by administered pricing behavior.41 They observed that transaction prices rather than quoted prices were the relevant measures of exchange price,42 and demonstrated that prices in concentrated industries were not as inflexible as previously supposed.43 Some authors have supported the idea that a large number of businesses price on a simple "cost plus" basis.44 A 1958 Brookings study described the pricing policies of twenty of the largest U.S. firms.' They observed five goals of pricing: 1. A target return on investment. 2. Stable prices and markups over cost. 3. A specified market share. 4. A competitive position. 5. Compete by taking advantage of product differences.45 These authors took the position that many large, powerful firms seem not to be overwhelmingly controlled by the market, yet they do not dominate the market.45 71 Lanzillotti took the position that firms start with a rate Of return that they consider satisfactory and then set a price which will allow them to earn that return when their plant utilization was at some "standard" rate.47 Weston felt that this position was an over-simplifi- cation. Pricing policies are not made apart from other business decisions, and firms are substantially "constrained" by the market mechanism according to Weston.48 Perceived Price That perceived price and actual price may differ is an important consumer phenomenon which is also relevant to industrial markets. Much of the pricing literature concerns itself with the subjective, percep- tual nature of price. Lambert found relationships between perceptual differences and price selections.49 Monroe reviewed the literature in the area of psychological pricing, price consciousness, and perceived price quantity relationships. He concluded that a number of psycho- logical and other contextual factors may lead to a perception of price by the buyer that is different from the perception assumed by the seller.50 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case Several of these perspectives will be helpful in guiding research expectations. Adelman's argument that the use of gross margin "offers great advantages in simplicity and accuracy" and that it "mirrors all the forces of demand and cost that impinge upon the distributive operation"51 was accepted for use in this study. No attempt was made to ascertain prices and costs in terms of their dollar levels. Instead, motor carrier management was asked about operating ratios and about the level of their prices in relation to costs and to the bureau tariffs that would ordinarily apply to the traffic. 72 The discussion of administered prices and pricing goals other than profit maximization should serve to mitigate the use of the economists profit maximizing assumption when viewing the pricing behavior of motor carriers. Carrier behavior may be guided by strategic concerns, cn~Inay be constrained by irrational adherence to pricing rules of thumb. Manipulation of the perception of price might also be expected. The subtle perceptual manipulations found in consumer marketing do not seem as probable as pricing behavior which utilizes an understanding of the interactions involved in multiple buyer influence. Some ways of presenting a price are more likely be be accepted by a traffic manager, others by a logistics or distribution manager, and so forth. Issues in Regulatopy Economics This study also provides an opportunity to collect observations relevant to broader regulatory issues, which while reflected in the motor carrier debate, go well beyond it. An examination of motor carrier pricing behavior in the wake of a substantial deregulation proves the opportunity to compare patterns of behavior with those predicted by various theories of regulation, or positions on the effects of regulation. Reschenthaler has provided an overview of several issues and positions in regulatory economics.52 A condensed version of his list of 18 items comprises Figure 3-1. Reschenthaler also identifies a fairly unified set of positions on these issues as being derived from the "Chicago School" scholars. He uses Trebing's listing of the principles of the Chicago School group.54 73 Figure 3-1 Some Issues in Regulatory Economics (Reschenthaler) Commission Independence (Legislation) Regulatory commissions may be captured by the regulated industry; therefore acting to protect the regulated firms from the func- tioning of the market. Commission Independence (Staff) Workers may move back and forth between the commission and its regulated firms. Capitalization of the Consumers Interest Consumers are unlikely to be able to organize to protect their interests against those of better organized special interest groups. The Adjudicatory Framework As commissions use an adversarial system, it fails if all important interest groups are not represented. Financing Boards may be underfinanced as a result of insufficient political constituency. The Protective Umbrella Regulatory agencies may also "promote" the health of the regulated industry. The Size of the Task Some industries may be so large or complex as to make effective regulation impractical. The Dimensions of the Product Attempts on the part of a regulatory agency to prevent monopoly pricing behavior may be frustrated by reducing quality, service or the adoption of accounting procedures to hide profit. Over Investment A permitted rate of return exceeding the cost of capital will give the firm an incentive to over invest. 74 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. Figure 3-1 (Continued) Some Issues in Regulatory Economics (Reschenthaler) Dynamic Efficiency Technological change and productivity may be slower as regulation leaves little incentive to innovate. Profit Focus Regulation by allowable profit may discourage improvements in efficiency. Political Pricing Gaining of political support may be a criterion which supersedes economic efficiency. Innovation in Pricing The regulatory process may discourage innovative pricing. The Deregulation Dilemma The license to operate may assume a market value under a regulatory scenario. Deregulation may force the write-off of these assets. The Perpetual Agency The tendency for a regulatory group once established to perpetuate itself. Political Accountability Regulatory commissions may engage in essentially political resource allocation decisions without owing political responsibility. Cross Subsidization Economic regulation may result in two cross-subsidy problems: A. Subsidizing some customers by overcharging others. 8. Use of same equipment to compete with non-regulated indus- tries. Costs and Benefits The costs of administering regulatory programs may exceed their benefits.5 75 Not all of Trebing's list would apply to motor carriers, so only those components which appear to apply are reproduced as Figure 3-2. Figure 3-2 Some Chicago School Positions (Trebing) Regulation of transport, broadcasting, natural gas and banking have been used in a restrictive and protective fashion in the United States Regulation can provide control over entry, restriction of availability of substitutes, and price stability; but potential costs to the firm in the form of time delays, loss of maneu- verability, and the possibility of extraneous public interest considerations may arise. A firm's attitude toward regulation reflects its maximization of an objective function which includes these potential benefits and costs. Government planning and market control are inferior to a market unconstrained by government influence. Much regulation involves disguised taxation and subsidization. Any relationship between market concentration and market power is discounted as are all aspects of Oligopolistic interdepen- dence. The issue of cross subsidization is not a significant economic problem. Problems associated with imbalance in power between different classes or groups of customers is ignored or dismissed. The costs of regulation are to be controlled explicitly or implicitly with competitive market solutions or with a natural monopoly whose excess earnings are neutralized by competitive bidding or an excess profits tax. i Commission regulation cannot be reformed. i l Government regulation and other exercises of government power result in economic distortions which are the sources of most! economic problems.55 I I l l l 76 Arrayed against this relatively unified Chicago School of thought is what Reschenthaler classifies as "a heterogeneous - in terms of ideology - group of legal, political science, and economic writers who foresee rejection of the major type of deregulation which the Chicagoans advocate for the economy."55 The Research Focus in a Regulatory Context In the context of these issues, this study undertakes a limited but important examination. While reflecting the competitive as opposed to the olgopolistic pricing behavioral assumptions, the primary research questions also address adjustments in the dimensions of the product (Figure 3-1, Item 8) as well as innovation in pricing (Figure 3-1, Item 13). Research question 4 has been operationalized to include "price/- service" innovation as well as pricing innovation more narrowly construed.57 Such technological innovations as the acquisition of more efficient equipment have been included, so the issue of dynamic efficiency (Figure 3-1, Item 10) is also considered. The cross subsidy issue is reflected in research question 3 where cross subsidy is interpreted as subsidizing some customers by overcharging others (Figure 3-1, Item 17A). Posner has characterized this as a form of taxation.58 Another result of forced cross subsidy may be the phenomenon of "cream skimming" or competitive entry in the markets where the comnon carrier was expected to make up his profit. Protection of common carriers by controlling such entry was a part of the rationale of the Act of 1935.59 Research question 3 examines the state of cross subsidy in deregulated trucking and compares that with executives' reports of the previous state of cross subsidy behavior. The study also focuses on the question of whether the firms' attitude toward deregulation reflects "its maximization of an objective 77 function" (Figure 3-2, Item 8) which includes such benefits of regu- lation as entry and price control and such costs as time delay and loss of flexibility.50 In this context, the conformance of the data with expectations derived from the Stigler theory will be examined.51 Stigler postulates that, "as a rule regulation is acquired by the industry and is designed and operated primarily for its benefit."52 This is in contrast with the view that regulation is for the benefit of the public, or is a political process which "defies rational explana- ‘tion....."53 In Stigler's view, industries seek to use the power of the state to obtain direct subsidy, control the entry of new rivals, to suppress substitutes and encourage complements, or to fix the level of price.54 If the Stigler theory were correct, we would expect trucking firms to have opposed the deregulation of entry and price prior to the deregulation; we would expect that profitability will have declined since the deregulation and that the trucking executives remain as ‘opposed to deregulation Now as they had been prior to the motor carrier act. The research explores these relationships. Kahn sees the association between regulation and restraint of competition as closely linked to two characteristics that the regulatory process exhibits in practice, protectionism and conservatism.55 Protectionism reflects the issue cited above as the "protective um- brella" or the tendency for the regulatory comnission to "promote" the regulated industry. This, in turn, may be a result of the kind of subtle influence that is derived from a lack of "legislative or staff independence." Conservatism reflects the regulatory values of predict- ability, continuity and planning, which may be threatened by the independent competitive maneuverings of private firms.55 78 Application to the Motor Carrier Industry Case The Motor Carrier Act of 1935 is characterized by Kahn as the "imposition of this comprehensive set of public utility-type controls on a highly dispersed and competitive industry."57 Its initial motivation was seen not only in terms of the requirement of a high level of service, but in terms of protecting the railroads from motor carrier competition and protecting the motor carriers from one another.68 Kahn does not believe that a deregulated trucking industry would be subject to destructive competition because of the high variable costs, low investment, and high mobility which characterize the firms.59 In the light of Kahn's analysis, the motor carrier industry would be a logical place to view the applicability of the Stigler theory. Research expectations are straightforwardly derived. It would be expected that trucking industry executives had opposed the legislation and perhaps actively worked against it prior to its passage. It would be expected that the firm would be less profitable after the passage of the act, and it would be expected that trucking executives both cur- rently oppose the act and support efforts to retard or roll back the deregulation process. Research expectations may also be derived from other regulatory issues discussed. In the context of the innovative arguments, it would be expected that firms are now more innovative both in terms of pricing behaviors narrowly defined, and in terms of price/service combinations when regulation is removed (Research Question 4). It would be expected that cross subsidy would be eliminated by competitive entry (Research Question 3) and that Oligopoly pricing behavior would have given way to more nearly competitive pricing behavior; resulting in price reductions and discounting (Research Question 2). 79 This in combination with a recognition of industry and shipper heterogeneity would result in the expectation of a market environment which placed a premium on the individualistic matching of heterogeneous supply with heterogeneous demand. This should result in more indi- vidualistic pricing behavior (Research Question 1). If Kahn's view of the applicability of the competitive model to the "trucking industry" in general does not apply to the regular route conmon carriers of general commodities, with their higher fixed costs, greater return to size,70 and lower mobility, then some deviation from these expected results may eventually be expected for this carrier group. Sumnary: Theoretical Analysis A theoretical analysis of the problem has yielded several important perspectives. First, extensive entry and price control is more diffi- cult to defend in situations where it can be argued that the industry is structured competitively than where the industry presents a situation of few sellers or Oligopoly. Secondly, a move toward greater competitive- ness in this industry situation is likely to be accompanied by price reductions, elimination of cross subsidy, and greater innovation. Third, recognition of essential heterOgeneity of supply and demand brings with it the expectation of individualistic pricing behavior in a deregulated environment. Fourth, the regular route common carriers of general commodities comprise a group which shows the potential for deviation from the competitive model. Fifth, this deviation may take the form of Oligopoly price behavior such as price leadership, rule of thumb, focal point, or limit pricing. Sixth, the bureau tariff struc- ture provides a logical and convenient vehicle for these pricing behaviors. Seventh, pricing behavior can be expected to deviate from 80 profit maximization and utilize manuevers for perceptual effect. Eighth, conglomerate ownership of regular route common carriers of general comnodities may view substandard returns in this business unit as being justified by the future possibility of successful Oligopoly pricing behavior. And finally, the deregulation provides an Opportunity to study attitudes and behaviors in the context of Stigler's view that regulation benefits the industry. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS This section examines empirical evidence relevant to the study. Evidence supporting the idea that the deregulation would have compet- itive effects is examined first. This is followed by an examination of evidence suggesting that other than competitive effects might be obtained. Results are then presented which are relevant to the Stigler position concerning interest groups and motor carrier regulation. Finally, research concerning the state of the market matching process in the motor carrier industry is reviewed. Evidence Suggesting Competitive Effects The empirical evidence suggesting that the pricing effects of deregulation might be competitive in nature is of many varieties. There have been examinations of aggregate industry structure and costs, examinations of deregulated trucking and comparisons with the regulated sector, examinations of overseas experience, and initial observations of actual effects. Each of these classifications will be reviewed. Industry Structure and Costs Early studies provided evidence that the trucking industry, when viewed in the aggregate, demonstrated a structure in substantial 81 conformance with the requirements for competition. Meyer et. al. cited low levels of concentration.71 Early studies of economies of scale, as provided byNelson72 and Roberts73 supported the idea that the industry was competitively structured by demonstrating no economies of scale to be present. These early studies analyzed, through cross sectional accounting data, the cost structures of a sample of firms in the industry.74 A recent review'of the economies of scale argument and research is provided by Sugrue et. al.75 The question of whether the no economy of scale research findings of the 1950's are, in fact, obsolete is still argued in 1982.76 Sugrue et. al supported the idea that the early findings were still valid. Their research included a study of the relationships (linear regressions) between the independent variable of revenue and the dependent variables of expense per vehicle mile, expense per ton mile, operating ratio and several others.77 The study group consisted of 531 Class I and II common carriers of general commodities. Sugrue et. al concluded that "this study ... finds no significant economies of scale in a major sector of the U.S. motor freight in- dustry."78 Examinations of Deregulated Trucking and Comparisons with Regulated Trucking Moore agreed that there were no substantial economies of scale in trucking.79 He also provided an estimate of the societal costs of regulation.80 In order to do this, he required an estimate of rate level change upon deregulation. His estimate of the rate level change that would occur in the motor carrier industry was based upon the assumption that rates would fall 20% as they had in the deregulation of certain agricultural commodities. On this basis, Moore had estimated a 82 loss in the common carrier truck sector of between $1.4 and $1.9 billion.31 Lamkin's 1973 analysis of aggregate secondary data for exempt carriers was used to examine structure, conduct and performance in the agricultural (non-regulated) sector of U.S. trucking.82 Lamkin noted that the exempt sector in 1960 was composed of almost twice as many firms as those in the regulated sector.83 In addition, these firms were of smaller size.34 Lamkin compared concentration ratios, noting that among intrastate Kansas carriers, the four largest comnon carriers (10.8% of carriers reporting revenue) controlled 83.0% of the market.85 In the agricultural exempt sector, only 15.7% of the farm to market carriage was controlled by the four largest firms; and in this sector, the four largest firms represented only 1.0% of the firms.85 Lamkin then examined market conduct of the exempt sector. He found selling prices well below those in published tariffs.37 Lamkin sumnarized his investigation as follows: The available data indicate that shipping charges are lower under the exemption than they would be if the industry were regulated. Miklius, Casavant, and Huang approached the question of the entry, exit, and survival rates of motor carriers in a deregulated trucking industry by comparing these rates in the exempt sector of motor carriage with similar rates for a large number of non-regulated industries.89 Miklius et. al. sought answers to the question of whether or not excessive entry would lead to excessive price cutting (cutthroat or destructive competition) resulting in a large number of exits.90 The analysis of data lead Miklius et. al. to conclude that "it does not appear that exempt motor carrier entry or exit rates are significantly higher than similar rates of other unregulated industries."91 83 Sloss attempted to predict the rate effects of a deregulation by examining rate behavior of trucking firms operating in differing provinces of Canada. The logic was that regulation differed suffi- ciently between the provinces so as to create an opportunity to study "regulating" vs. "non regulating" provinces.92 Sloss accepted a definition of transportation price as rate per ton mile,93 and structured his analysis to test the relationship of transport rates to selected Operating costs of motor carriers in the various markets.94 The central hypothesis was that in "regulating" provinces the rates received by intercity trucking firms exceeded those of firms providing services in "non regulating" provinces after con- sidering differences in cost.95 Sloss concluded that, after adjustment for costs, the rates in regulated provinces appeared higher.96 Similar studies have followed the Sloss contribution, with Palmer97 and McLachlin98 building upon the work and coming to similar conclusions concerning the Canadian situation, although Sloss in later work did not duplicate his findings.99 Allen et. al . attempted the prediction of rate results of dereg- ulation through an examination of the unregulated intrastate trucking experience in New Jersey.100 Rate behavior was studied using both phone and mail surveys of shippers and carriers together with an analysis of secondary data.101 Allen found that "lower intrastate rates for comparable comnodities, distances and weights are a major conclusion of this study."102 Several other important relationships are to be found among Allen's conclusions. Strictly intrastate (non-regulated) carriers were found to be healthier on an operating ratio basis (88.11) than I.C.C. certified 84 carriers operating in the intrastate New Jersey market (95.92).103 Allen offered the ideas that non-union labor, more truckload work or the entry of more efficient carriers might account for this.104 Allen also found that the majority of carriers were in favor of the deregulated New Jersey status quo,105 as well as the I.C.C. status quo, despite the substantial differences between these two regulatory environments.105 Allen offered the explanation that "this may reflect the phenomenon of status quoism, i.e. one is happy and secure when one has learned to play the game."107 This perspective might provide a useful alternative to the Stigler perspective. Examination of Overseas Experience Some examinations of previous overseas experience also pointed toward satisfactory competitive effects. For example, Nelson conducted an empirical study of the effects of transport deregulation in Australia.108 Nelson found that under free entry conditions and unregulated minimum rates: 1. Excessive competition did not prevail, except transitionally and when total demand temporarily falls off cyclically. Even under these circumstances, returns of carriers do not go to such low levels that facilities and service become inadequate and service of poor quality. 2. Truck services improve under competition. 3. Rural areas and markets do not lose the services and competitive rates that their traffic demands justify. 4. Road and rail modes developed integrated operations and services. 5. Rates are lower in relation to cost of service.109 85 Nelson and Whitten's 1977 study of deregulation in Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Great Britain, Japan, and the common market lead 111 similar conclusions. Also summarized in chapter two above, the Nelson and Whitten study noted satisfactory competitive results of the British deregulation, drawing the conclusion that an industrial economy can have stable and profitable motor goods carriers and adequate and efficient road freight service without restrictive entry and rate controls.110 Observed Effects of MCA 1980 in Contemporary Literature Preliminary results of the deregulation of 1980 have found their way into the literature and appear to confirm an initial move toward Inore competitive behavior, but this must be evaluated in the context of the recessionary economy of 1980-1982. Can the price effects of recession be separated from the price effects of deregulation? Temple, Barker, and Sloane observed that there was no evidence to suggest widespread rate discounts during the 1970 and 1974-75 recessions,111 while a 1982 FTC study found discounting of both LTL and TL traffic during 1981 to be "rampant."112 There has also been some evidence of entry. During the first year under the motor carrier act, almost 2,500 new firms entered the in- dustry, primarily to handle truckload traffic, 30,000 applications for extended operating authority (five times the normal number) were submitted, and 95.4 percent were approved. During this time approxi- mately 50 trucking firms were given authority to serve 48 states and the large LTL carriers aggressively expanded into each other's territory.113 Two studies of the effects of MCA 1980 have been contributed by Corsi, Tuck, and Gardner. One focused upon minority owned motor 86 carriers.114 The results of this survey research indicated that rate cutting was a reality, although a surprisingly large number responded to the effect that the rate provisions of the act had as yet no effect upon their business.115 Corsi et. al. focused a second survey on owner operators.115 Large numbers (47.3%) of owner operators reported reductions in rates. Corsi et. al. solicited opinions on the results of MCA 1980 and found that, with respect to the provisions designed to create a more competitive environment, owner operators were "over- whelmingly negative"117 although much of this attitude might be attributed to the economic downturn. In 1981, Harper conducted a survey of motor carriers and shippers regarding the consequences of the 1980 act.118 Harper found support for the hypothesis that the I.C.C. had created a situation where the market, rather than the regulatory system, was determining such things as entry, rates, and quality of service.119 Harper also found support for hypotheses to the effect that motor carriers were placing more emphasis upon marketing, cost control, efficiency, planning, and innovation while shippers were placing greater emphasis on negotiating skill, new rate service ideas, and transportation, or logistics management.120 Harper sought but did not find adequate support for a hypothesis to the effect that the deregulation had resulted in poorer service and higher rates for certain undesirable types of traffic.”1 Harper characterized his study as preliminary in nature because of the "relatively short time which had elapsed since the onset of liberalized policies"122 and because one "cannot separate the effects of regulatory change from the effects of the poor economy on shippers and carriers."123 The Interstate Commerce Commission has also generated studies which present some evidence of competitive effects. In a recent staff report, 87 post deregulation activities of the motor carrier industry were high- lighted.124 Truckers were found to be filing an increased number of new rates, discounting, and offering innovative pricing schemes.125 However, this activity was set against the background of general rate increases of between 1.5 and 6.2 percent on TL shipments and 6.2 and 10 percent on LTL shipments as adjusted by the rate bureaus in April, 1982.125 Applications for operating authority were up since-the motor carrier act, with a resulting growth in the absolute number of carriers in each carrier size category.127 Growth extended to general commodity carriers, with 271 nationwide general commodity applications having been received under the act as of May 21, 1982.128 Evidence also existed of increased investment in terminal facilities and route extensions.129 In a parallel G.A.O. study of the effects of the 1980 act upon the household goods moving industry, several examples of price discounts, price innovation, and service innovation were found.130 Summary: Evidence of Competitive Effects Much empirical evidence exists to support the idea that the results Of the deregulation will be competitive. The aggregate structure of the industry appears to be competitive, experience with deregulated trucking and comparisons with regulated trucking appear to support the idea that regulation imposes higher rates, overseas experience with motor carrier deregulation has been generally satisfactory, and some observations of initial effects appear to be in line with the expectations of the competitive model. Evidence Suggesting Other Than Competitive Effects Substantial empirical evidence has also been offered to support the idea that the effects of a deregulation may not be competitive, or at 88 least not competitive in all segments of the industry or in the long run. This evidence may be classified as observations which call into question competitive assumptions that may have been made, observations demonstrating a potential for higher rates, observations of the overseas experience suggesting a potential for increased concentration in some segments, and preliminary observations of the actual effects of dereg- ulation. These are reviewed in turn. Problems with Competitive Assumptions Some problems have been found with competitive assumptions. In a review of previous work, Nupp took the position that the empirical question of structure had not really been resolved in this industry.131 Noting that regulatory design must be conditioned by the structures of markets and supply systems of the industries being regulated, Nupp stated that "economic research has as yet reached no satisfactory conclusion concerning the structure of the market or its supplier."132 Dicer's review of previous studies concerning economies of scale lead lrhn to several critical perspectives concerning the application of the approach.133 Dicer identified a substantial problem with this analysis as the service homogeneity assumption.134 Comparison of costs between large and small firms is only valid if those costs are attrib- utable to the production of comparable products. Dicer wondered whether common carriage was comparable to contract carriage, or whether common carriage was comparable within its own classification.”5 Dicer suggested that lumping firms of different types together would be misleading,136 and suggested that there were forces leading to economies of scale in the industry: 89 l. Indivisible factors of production such as those used for coordi- nation, information, communication and modern rate determination, billing and scheduling. 2. Unique relationships between carriers and shippers, with large shippers preferring to deal with carriers which can fit into their patterns of operations (wide market coverage, etc.).137 He also identified forces leading to diseconomies of scale.138 Problems involved with growth such as effective management practices, capital availability, labor problems, and improper technology were cited.139 Dicer concluded: ...that the application of economic theory concerning economies of scale and Optimum size in the specific area of the motor carrier industry is not the simple matter that it appears to be at first... A few fundamental conclusions can be drawn: (1) any study dealing with the motor carrier industry must face the problem of hetero- geneity and treat the "industry" as a group of sub- industries; (2) the relevant cost curves are of a complex nature, and for the determination of optimum size, extreme care must be observed that an absolute minimum is observed rather than a relative minimum on the curve; and (3) any type of analysis must consider the dynamic character of the industry for policy to be effective.140 Even using a conventional definition of economies of scale, the results do not appear to have stabilized. For example, in 1977, Koenker conducted a study of operating and financial data for a sample of 25 interstate common carriers of general freight operating in five mid- western states.141 A cost function was estimated for three distance and weight categories where the output was measured in millions of ton miles per year.”2 The average costs per ton mile were found to be at their minimum in the 6-8 million ton mile per annum size range, which is smaller than most firms in the U.S. trucking industry.143 This result would suggest increasing economies of scale up to this relatively small size, followed by decreasing economies of scale. 9O Rakowski sumarized the contractory economies of scale findings in 1977.144 Roberts,145 Nelson,145 and Meyer147 had supported the constant returns to scale position, but Patton148 had indicated efficiency differences between sizes. The findings of Ladenson and Stoga149 and those of Emery150 also indicated that there were scale economies in the industry. Rakowski cited Dicer (sunmarized above) as having given the best analysis of the methodological problems involved in analyzing the essentially heterogeneous trucking industry.151 Rakowski's own 1977 analysis of secondary data for 32 trucking firms152 indicated that when a simple least squares regression was applied to the plots of 1) revenue vs. operating income, 2) assets vs. operating income, and 3) net worth vs. operating income, where the firms considered ranged from $10 million to $600 million in revenue, the smallest and the largest firms fell above the regression line, while the mid-sized firms fell below it.153 Rakowski concluded that "the analysis of eConomies of scale in trucking has no simple answers. This paper has found that the performance of various sized trucking firms seems to result in a discontinuous function."154 In a later work, Rakowski chose a larger sample of Class I and Class II carriers conforming to instruction 27 (at least 75% of revenue from intercity operations) which also reported at least 98% of their revenue from intercity operations.”5 This resulted in a study of 371 firms. The results of this expanded study indicated "definite cost differences and economies of scale in trucking"156 but not such that one may generalize across trucking as a homogeneous activity.157 Within subgroups, Rakowski's conclusions were: 91 1. The short haul segment of the motor carrier universe, which is dominated by smaller firms, shows increasing profitability and declining costs. 2. The long haul segment, which is heavily dominated by the giant motor carriers, shows economies in profit but not in cost. 3. In the middle areas of trucking there are no apparent trends hi either cost or profit level.158 Rakowski hypothesized that the data produced "additional evi- dence"159 for a thread of thought presented in the literature by Dicer150 and Wyckoff151 such that there may be a number of critical phases as a firm grows in size.152 The research conducted by Maze provides a basis to question the applicability of the information assumption of the competitive model.163 Maze undertook an analysis of secondary data and a mail survey of trucking firms, drivers, and inspection stations in the unregulated Florida environment. Maze summarized one important finding as follows: Those large carriers that survive and flourish in the Florida market possess the information to "skim" high return loads. Remaining loads are carriedlgy information. poor carriers, espeCTally owner operators. Perhaps information in the deregulated environment will be in- adequate to ensure competitive effects in each ecological niche. In summary, there is substantial evidence to support the idea that the competitive model may not apply, owing to deviations from the model found in the industry itself. The output of the industry may not be sufficiently homogeneous to allow comparison of costs, the economies of scale arguments have not stabilized, and the information assumptions iri the model do not seem to hold. 92 The Potential for Higher Rates Some empirical work has been directed at the possibility that rates may be higher in an unregulated environment. Maister155 undertook a criticism of the research track begun by Sloss.166 Maister had criticized this research track on the grounds of the imprecise treatment of regulation that Sloss had utilized.157 In Maister's early work, he had been unable to replicate the results of Sloss, Palmer, and McLachlin.168 In Maister's more recent work, he was able to replicate the results.159 Maister considered these findings unstable and drew the following conclusions: -The major explanation for this instability of results is, of course, the problem of model specification. The model used in ‘this paper (and in all previous research on this topic) is a very rough approximation of a cost model... -Such a procedure may be criticized on at least three major grounds. First, the cost model omits many important vari- ables...(mix of contract and common carriage, service levels, geographic conditions, traffic balance). -The second major weakness of this research tradition is the failure to take into account demand conditions in each of the jurisdictions under investigation ("explaining price by con- structing a supply equation"). -The third major weakness of the approach is the difficulty of accurately capturing the realities of what is termed "regula- tion."1 0 Beyond criticism of the methodology, Maister felt he could draw some conclusions about the effects of regulation on price: It would now appear that there is some evidence to support the conclusion that, for some commodities, regulation in Canada has had a perceptible influence on rate levels while for others this influence is not detectable.171 Thus, Maister diluted the conclusions of the research track begun by Sloss considerably. Chow was to go further. Beyond diluting the 93 argument that regulation was associated with higher prices, Chow was to find an association of regulation with lower prices. Chow found the variety of regulatory structures among states in the United States to be an opportunity to study the price effects of motor carrier deregulation.172 In general, the states themselves had made attempts to review their own regulation policies. Chow reviewed the state studies finding that the Sloss study and the Allen et. al. New Jersey study (both above) had provided the empirical basis for many of them.173 He felt that a good comparison would be between rates for comparable services in several states, with states reflecting different regulatory conditions.174 Following this logic, Chow performed a regression study using rate as the dependent variable and distance, fuel tax, weight limits, license fees, wage rates, dry bulk fertilizer consumption (the commodity under study), seasonality of that consumption and dummy variables for inflation and regulation. His results indicated an association between regulation and 1239: rates. Chow concluded: No single policy direction such as "less regulation" or "more regulation" may be appropriate. The best policy for each segment of trucking and for the economic conditions inlggfferent transport markets may differ substantially. The analysis of the relationship between Canadian provincial regulation or U.S. state regulation and the level of motor carrier rates was now at best confusing. Sloss, Palmer, and McLachlan had pointed in the direction of higher rates associated with regulation. Maister had not been able to consistently replicate their results, and Chow had found at least one formulation of the problem which pointed in the other direction. 94 Overseas Experience While the analysis of overseas experience was generally favorable toward deregulation, certain less Optimistic perspectives may also be derived from the studies. For example, Nelson's analysis of transport deregulation in Australia includes the observation that concentration has increased among multimodal freight forwarders.175 LeClerc's discussion of freight competition observes that the Australian "dereg- ulation has ended with a large number of small truckers, but with only a few very large intercity operators or freight forwarders who dominate the industry."177 The potential for concentration, as discussed by Wyckoff,178 may be coming to fruition in Australia. Observed Effects of M.C.A. 1980 in Contemporacpriterature Not all of the preliminary observations of the effects of the U.S. deregulation point toward conformance with the competitive model. The recent I.C.C. study, discussed above, while identifying many competitive behaviors on the part of trucking firms also identifies other trends.179 Some carriers have placed advertisements in trade journals directed at owners and C.E.O.S. of other motor carriers. These advertisements have suggested that the carriers "get smart and recognize that (through low rate schemes) you are killing yourself, the industry, your company, and your competitors."180 The rate bureaus continue to function and to push through substantial rate increases.181 Few of the applications for nationwide general commodity authority have been received from new carriers,182 and substantial acquisition and consolidation behavior has been documented within the general commodity group.183 In this context, it is possible that competitive pricing behavior on the part of regular route comnon carriers of general comodities may be an interim phase. 95 Summary: Other Than Competitive Effects In summary, there is some evidence to support the argument that the results of deregulation will not be in accordance with the competitive inodel ‘Hl all segments of the trucking industry. This evidence includes the difficulty of measuring market structure given the nature of transportation markets and the resulting questions concerning real structure on a market by market basis. It also includes contradictory evidence concerning the economies of scale assumption, the heterogeneity of industry output, the weakness of the perfect information assumption, and confusing results concerning the relationship of rates to the level ' of state or province regulation. Beyond weaknesses in the competitive assumptions (or market imperfections),certain structural patterns in overseas deregulation and certain behavioral patterns in the U.S. deregulation point to a potential for Oligopolistic pricing behavior among regular route common carriers of general commodities. The Australian experience includes concentration among large intercity Operators and the American experience includes some evidence of attempts to make competitors aware of Oligopolistic interdependence, continuation of the bureau tariff structure, perhaps as a "focal point" or as a component of a "rule of thumb" formula, and some merger activity. Evidence: Interest Groups and Regulation in Transportation In the context of broad regulatory issues, a primary focus of this study is the Stigler perspective. In the motor carrier industry context, this perspective would expect that motor carrier management and aligned interest groups would have opposed the deregulation based upon their understanding of their own economic interest. A considerable body of evidence exists concerning the positions taken by interest groups on 96 the issue of motor carrier regulatory reform. This section considers Stigler's work with the motor carrier industry, work which establishes the political positions of different groups with regard to motor carrier deregulation, and work which analyses the political process involved in the establishment, retention or modification of motor carrier regulation. Stigler Stigler used the motor carrier industry as an example of an industry which had acquired two of the four possible favorable govern- mental policies. The list of four included: direct subsidy, entry control, retardation of substitutes, and price controls. The motor carrier industry had achieved entry and price control. Stigler con- trasted the declining numbers of licensed carriers in operation between 1946 and 1966 with the growing numbers of cumulative applications to operate during the same period, and noted the effect of price control upon rates of return in the industry.184 The early evolution of motor carrier regulation provided Stigler with a quantitative illustration. Hypothesizing that the railroads would try to influence the emerging state regulation of trucking iii the late 205 and 305, Stigler believed that the pattern of truck weight limits would "emerge in response to the economic interests of the concerned parties." Thus he expected that: 1. Heavy trucks would be allowed in states with a substantial number of trucks on farms. 2. The longer the average railroad haul the less the railroads would oppose trucks (truck is a stronger competitor in short hauls). 97 3. The public would be concerned by the potential damage to the highway system and thus, the better the highway system the heavier the trucks.185 Stigler performed regressions in support of this analysis using the weight limits on trucks as the dependent variable, and the number of trucks on farms per 1,000 persons in the agricultural labor force, the average length of railroad freight haul in miles, and the percent of state highways with "high" type surface as explanatory variables.135 The three explanatory variables were statistically significant and worked in the expected directions.187 Positions of Groups Much of the research which established positions of groups prior to the deregulation may be viewed as supportive of the Stigler perspective. Harper and Johnson's 1974 study reviewed several of the established positions. The AInerican Trucking Association was clearly against any relaxation of entry control or rate regulation.188 The Department of Transportation was very much in favor of liberalized regulation, and the I.C.C. was opposed.189 The views of the shipper were considered by Harper in 1974. His earlier research had found that traffic managers believed the results of regulation to be satisfactory,190 while previous research by Nelson had found that shipper top management was strongly against regulation, at the same time that traffic managers "showed little enthusiasm for a reduction in regulation."191 Harper's 1974 study evaluated the opinions of two groups of shipper executives; transportation and non transportation. His conclusions included the observations that transportation executives were beginning 98 to favor reduced regulation and that executives of large firms were more likely to favor deregulation than executives of small firms.192 In a 1976 study, Davis et. al. compared perceptions of transporta- tion regulation and deregulation issues held by members of two different professional groups, the National Council of Physical Distribution Management (NCPDM) and the American Society of Traffic and Transporta- tion (AST&T).193 Davis et. al. evaluated the differences in these groups as deriving from an "inventory and customer service perspective" (NCPDM) versus a "traffic and transportation perspective" (AST&ST).194 Substantial differences in the view of deregulation were found. NCPDM respondents generally favored some deregulation, while AST&T members generally did not.195 Constantin et. al. conducted a mail survey of rail carriers, motor carriers, and shippers in order to compare their responses on regulatory issues.195 Sending questionnaires to members of Delta Nu Alpha and the AST&T, Constantin et. al. divided responses according to the employment of the respondent as rail carrier, motor carrier, or shipper. All three groups disagreed with the statement that the regulatory process should be repealed and agreed that the then current (1977) system should be improved rather than "having deregulation."197 All three groups also agreed that deregulation would impair service to small towns.198 Jerman et. al. identified groups according to whether they were affiliated with "pro" (extended regulation) positions or "anti" (less regulation) positions.199 This classification is shown in Figure 3-3.200 They also sumarized the findings of earlier survey research. Among the findings summarized were: 1. Strong carrier support for collective pricing. 2. Satisfaction of traffic managers with the current (1977) system.201 99 These authors found both shippers and carriers agreeing with the idea that entry controls should be retained, when the question was phrased as "allowing anyone to enter the transportation business at will without the responsibilities and obligations now imposed upon common car- riers."202 Burck contributed to the understanding of positions on deregu- lations by publishing an interview with Bennett C. Whitlock, then president of the A.T.A., and James C. Miller III, then resident scholar and co-director of the Center for the Study of Government Regulaticwi at the American Enterprise Institute.203 Whitlock's position was that regulation had brought stability and reasonable rates without dis- crimination among shippers, regions, or communities.204 lfiller be- lieved that reform of trucking regulation would improve output, increase productivity, and have a moderating effect on the cost of living.205 Stock's mail survey of Class I and II common carriers (1979) reflected motor carrier beliefs that the government should administer equipment safety, market entry and exit, transport of hazardous ma- terials, carrier rights of way, and merger or acquisition activity.205 Nmst deregulation proposals were opposed by the carriers, and rate bureaus were defended as bringing stability to the rate structure.207 Many carriers took the position that "rate chaos"*w0uld result if rate bureaus were eliminated.208 The Political Process Ulen undertook a historical examination of the early evolution of the Interstate Commerce Commission.209 In line with the Stigler perSpective, Ulen identified three principle early demanders of federal railroad regulation. These were: 100 1. The farmers in the upper midwest., 2. Merchants and farmers in the east. 3. The railroads themselves (as the rail network became more dense and as competition thwarted attempts to collude on prices).210 Figure 3-3 VARIOUS VIEWPOINTS ON THE EXTENT TO WHICH REGULATION IS DESIRABLE (From Jerman et. al.) PRO ANTI Or Extended Regulation Or Significantly Less Regulation 1. Interstate Commerce 1. Last Two Presidential Commission Administrations (1977) 2. American Trucking 2. Department of Transportation Association 3. International Brotherhood 3. Railroads of Teamsters . 4. National Industrial 4. Group of Economists Traffic League 5. Water Transport Association 5. Ralph Nader 6. Farm Groups 6. Other Consumer and Environmental Advocates Ulen's analysis suggests that the early I.C.C. was ineffectual and that its existence was not as strong an explanatory factor in the success and failure of rail cartels as was the aggregate demand for transportation implicit in the business conditions of the periods examined.211 Ulen concluded that: The history of federal railroad regulation between 1887 and 1920 cannot be fully comprehended using either the public interest theory or the economic theory of regu- lation. 101 Ulen felt that none of the identified interest groups expressed a demand for later alterations to the act, extending the powers of the I.C.C. to the point achieved by 1920, and that "the only group which may have had sustained interest in the events from 1903 on was the I.C.C. itself."213 Stalon's case description of trucking regulation in Illinois supported a view of an industry in control of its regulation.214 He reported his findings based upon his empirical observations as a commissioner of the Illinois Comnerce Comnission (I.L.C.C.).215 From this perspective, the effects of the I.L.C.C. regulation of the trucking industry appeared to be: 1. To legitimatize the industry's collective ratemaking. 2. To generate an excess capacity in the industry (the law prevents an efficient peak-off peak pricing system so the industry responds by developing excess capacity). 3. To limit via rate and certification procedures one "very important dimension of competition, namely Schumpeterian 'creative destruc- tion' competition" (not price rivalry, but new forms of service and new organizations...stimulating efficiency and technological progress).216 Lieb's study of the attempt to relax motor carrier regulation in Massachusetts provides insight into the dynamics of the influence process.217 Lieb analyzed the interaction of shipper and carrier interests which caused the bill's defeat.218 In the Massachusetts case, strong opposition on the part of the motor carriers, together with apprehension among shippers as to the effects of regulatory change, provided sufficient political momentum to stifle the deregulation legislation.219. 102 Sumnary: Interest Groups and Regulation This transportation industry evidence does provide some support for the Stigler perspective. Certainly Stigler's own work,220 and the consistent motor carrier position as reflected in the work of Harper and Johnson,221 Constantin et. al.,222 Jerman et. al.,223 Burck,224 Stock,225 Stalon,226 and Lieb227 are supportive of the Stigler framework. But the Stigler framework comes short of explaining other observations. Why, for example, do the views of the NCPDM group differ from those of the ASTBT group,228 why did rail carriers occasionally side with motor carriers in opposing deregulation when they retain substantial monopoly power,229 why did the I.C.C. seem to take on an interest Of its own after 1903,230 and why did Allen's respondents231 (discussed in a previous section) favor both regulation and deregulation when each comprised the status quo in differing geographic environments? It would seem defensible to say, in this context, that the Stigler perspective makes a substantial contribution to the explanation of observations. But, it may be incomplete. "Rational" economic self interest may be mitigated by other factors. The Market Matching Process in the Motor Carrier Industry Recognition of the essential heterogeneity of the demand and supply characteristics of the industry brings with it the expectation that carriers will find a matching process to be adaptive in the deregulated environment. Many normative statements have been made concerning the application of a marketing perspective to the motor carrier industry. These would include contributions by Constantin et. al.,232 Potter and Wang,233 Schuster,234 Jerman et. al.,235 Rose and Zientara,235 8auer,237 Mossman and Maiers,238 and A. T. Kearney.239 Some of these adopt a 103 perspective compatible with Alderson's theoretical position, that of marketing as "matching."240 This group includes Constantin et. al. who suggested that carriers adOpt what they termed the "4 ms of market planning"; 1) measure market needs, 2) meeting market needs with carrier strengths, 3) "matching" market needs and carrier strengths, and 4) marketing to target market segments.241 Potter and Wang also saw the basic marketing functions in terms of a "matching" process. Firms are required to specify organizational Objectives, analyze the external environment, and program marketing activities.“2 This programing is seen to consist of 1) seeking customers, 2) "matching" their wants and desires with organizational capabilities, 3) designing programs to effectuate the "match", and 4) consumating the "match" by delivering the service.243 Beyond straightforward adoption Of Alderson's marketing as matching construction, several compatible normative views have been expressed. This group would include arguments for segmentation typified by those of Schuster,244 and Rose and Zientara,245 and by Mossman and Maiers' expectation of more "creative individually priced service"245 in the deregulated environment. Evidence: The Market Matching Process Empirical results would indicate that the state of the market matching process as practiced by motor carriers prior to the deregu- lation was not good. Even in the context of an extremely complex rate structure, there was evidence of price/service mismatch. The survey research of Jerman et. al. indicated that the responses of motor carriers and purchasing traffic managers were substantially different when they were asked to rate the importance of 26 motor carrier selec- 104 tion variables.247 Similarly, Robicheaux et. al. asked shippers to estimate service levels which were "reasonable to expect" in motor common carrier markets versus service levels actually experienced.“8 Satisfaction was inferred by subtracting each reported reasonable service level from each reported actual service level.“9 Importantly, it was found that there were substantial groups of shippers who were either oversatisfied or dissatisfied with motor comnon carrier perfor- mance.250 Reallocation of motor carrier service effort was recom- mended.251 Given this, it might be argued that the regulatory structure was placing constraints upon the matching process. Perhaps lack of com- petition had caused motor carrier management to be insensitive to the need for careful matching. Perhaps the specific Operational and rate constraints had prevented even the most market oriented management from adjusting their offering to precisely meet shipper requirements. The Study in the Context of the Literature In this context, the study examines pricing behavior following the lessening of legal constraints on both entry and pricing. The study examines pricing behavior in a segment of the industry which has been identified as possibly in poor conformance with the competitive model. The research questions reflect the competitive behavioral assumptions in the context of a recognition of essential heterogeneity, and the research investigates heterogeneous pricing behavior through taxonomy development. Finally, the study examines conformity of the political positions and behaviors of industry executives with the expectations of the Stigler theory. The research is conducted in the context of conflicting empirical evidence concerning the appropriateness of the competitive model for 105 description of the results of a deregulation of this industry segment, and in the context of empirical evidence which is not entirely explained by the Stigler model. The research views pricing in a marketing as well as an economic context, and is conducted in the third year following the deregulation; utilizing the first opportunity to begin the separa- tion of the results of deregulation from the results of economic recession. 106 Footnotes 1 These arguments have been reviewed in Chapter 2. For example, see Charles L. Dearing and Wilfred Owen, National Transportation Policy (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1949), p. 192 and pp. 362-78 for a discussion of the desirability of freer competition. See John R. Meyer, Merton J. Peck, John Stenason and Charles Zwick, IE Economics of Competition in the Transportation Industries (Cambridge, liass.: lHarvard UniVersity Press, 1964), p. 211-I9 fOr an evaluation of «Concentration. See also Dudley F. Pegrum, TranSportation Economics and Public Policy, 3rd ed. (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1973), pp. 122-23, 133-34, and 176-79 for a discussion of economies of scale, proportion of fixed costs, and ease of entry. 2 This argument is articulated by 0. Daryl Wyckoff, "Factors Promoting Concentration of Motor Carriers Under Deregulation," Trans- portation Research Forum 15 (1974): 1-6. 3 Jack Hirschleifer, Price Theory and Applications (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, Inc., 1976), p. 263. 4 C. E. Furguson and J. P. Gould, Microeconomic Theory, 4th ed. (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1975), p. 225. 5 See for example R. A. Nelson, "The Economic Structure of the Highway Carrier Industry in New England," Motor Freight Transport for New Epgland (Boston: New England Governors Cohference on Public Transportation, 1957). Also see Merrill J. Roberts, "Some Aspects of liotor Carrier Costs: Firm Size, Efficiency and Financial Health," Land Economics 32 (August 1956): 228-38. 5 Dudley F. Pegrum, Transportation Economics and Public Policy, 3rd ed. (Homewood, Ill.: Richard D. Irwin, 1973), p. 176. 7 Ibid., p. 177. 8 Pegrum cites Ford K. Edwards, "Cost Analysis in Transporta- tion,“ American Economic Review 2 (May 1947): p. 453. 9 Pegrum, p. 179. 10 Ibid. 11 Meyer et. al., The Economics of Competition..., pp. 211-13. 12 Furguson and Gould, p. 225. 13 John C. Spychalski, "Criticisms of Regulated Freight Transport: 00 Economists' Perceptions Conform with Institutional Realities?," Transportation Journal 14 (Spring 1975): 5-17. 14 Philip B. Schary, "Measuring Concentration and Competition in the Regulated Motor Carrier Industry," Transportation Journal 12 (Summer 1973): p. 52. 107 15 Spychalski, p. 6. 16 Ibid. 17 Ibid. 18 See also 0. Daryl Wyckoff, "Factors Promoting Concentration of Motor Carriers Under Deregulation," Transportation Research Forum 15 (1974): 1-6. 19 Ibid., p. 5. 20 Donald V. Harper, Transportation in America, 2nd ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall: Inc., 1982), p. 171. 21 Ibid. 22 Ibid. 23 Wroe Alderson, "The Analytical Framework for Marketing," in Marketing Classics, 4th ed., eds. Ben M. Enis and Keith K. Cox (Boston: Allyn and Bacon, Inc., 1981), p. 24. 24 Shelby D. Hunt, James A. Muncy, and Nina M. Ray, "Alderson's General Theory of Marketing: A Formalization," in Review of Marketing 1981, eds. Ben M. Enis and Kenneth J. Roering (Chicago: American Marketing Association, 1981), p. 269. 25 Ibid. 26 Ibid., p. 268. 27 Bernard J. LaLonde and Paul H. Zinzer, Customer Service: Meaning and Measurement (Chicago: National Council of Physical Distribution Management, 1976), p. 154. 23 George D. Wagenheim, "Distribution and Marketing Strategy," Nineteenth Annual Conference National Council of Physical Distribution Managementl(Chicago, NCPDM, 1981), pp. 852-59. 29 See for example the classification system for carriers in American Trucking Associations, Inc. Executive and Ownership Report Class I and II Motor Carriers of Property 1982 (Washington, D.C.: A.T.A., 1982), p. 11. 30 Harper W. Boyd, Jr. and Jean-Claude Larreche, "The Foundations of Marketing Strategy," in Review of Marketing 1978, eds. Gerald Zaltman and Thomas V. Bonoma (Chicago: American Marketifig Association, 1978), p. 42. 31 George S. Day, "Diagnosing the Product Portfolio," Journal of Marketing 41 (April 1977): 29-38. 32 William K. Hall, "Survival Strategies in a Hostile Environ- ment," Harvard Business Review 58 (Sept.-Oct. 1980): 75-85. 108 33 Yoram Wind and Vijay Mahajan, "Designing Product and Business Portfolios," Harvard Business Review 59 (Jan.-Feb. 1981): 155-57. 34 Ibid. 35 Robin Wensley, "Strategic Marketing: Betas, Boxes or Basics," Journal of Marketing 45 (Summer 1981): 173-82. 35 M. A. Adelman, "The 'Product' and 'Price' in Distribution," American Economic Review 47 (May 1957): 266-73. 37 Ibid., p. 273. 33 Gardner Means as characterized by Gilbert Burck, "The Myths and Realities of Corporate Pricing," Fortune, April 1972, p. 85. 39 Ibid., p. 85. 40 G. J. Stigler and J. K. Kindahl, The Behavior of Industrial Prices, as cited in Burck, p. 86. 41 George J. Stigler and James K. Kindahl, "Industrial Prices as Administered by Dr. Means," The American Economic Review 63 (September 1973): p. 717. 42 Burck, p. 85. 43 Ibid. 44 I. F. Pearce as cited by Burck, pp. 86-87. 45 A. D. H. Kaplan, Joel 8. Dirlam and Robert F. Lanzillotti, Pricing in Big Business (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1958), as cited by Burck, p. 88. 46 Ibid. 47 F. Lanzillotti in the American Economic Review, Dec. 1958, as cited by Burck, p. 88. 43 J. Fred Weston as cited by Burck, pp. 88-89. 49 Zarrel F. Lambert, "Price and Choice Behavior," Journal of Marketing Research 9 (February 1972): 35-40. 50 Kent 8. Monroe, "Buyers Subjective Perceptions of Price," Journal of MarketingyResearch 10 (February 1973): p. 78. 51 Adelman, p. 269. 52 G. B. Reschenthaler, "Direct Regulation in Canada: Some Policies and Problems," Logistics and Transportation Review 15 (1979): pp. 37-102. 109 53 This list is condensed from Reschenthaler, pp. 44-52. 54 Harry M. Trebing, "The Chicago School vs. Public Utility Regulation," Journal of Economic Issues 10 (March 1976): 97-113, as cited by Reschenthaler, p. 49. 55 Trebing, pp. 97-103. 55 Reschenthaler, p. 52. 57 Reschenthaler cites Richard A. Posner, "Natural Monopoly and Its Regulation," Stanford Law Review 21 (February 1969): p. 606, as taking the position that the regulatory process may discourage innova- tive pricing. The argument that regulation may, in some market struc- ture contexts, stifle innovation more broadly construed is based upon Scherer, pp. 424, 438. 53 Richard A. Posner, "Taxation By Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2 (Spring 1971): 22-50. 59 Alfred E. Kahn, The Economics of Re ulation: PrinciLles and Institutions Vol. 2 (New YoFk: John Wiley and* ons, 1971), p. B. 60 Trebing. 6'1 George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2 (Spring 1971): 3-21. 62 Ibid., p. 3. 63 Ibid. 64 Ibid. 65 Kahn, p. 11. 65 Ibid., p. 13. 67 Ibid., p. 14. 68 Ibid. 69 Ibid., p. 179. 70 Size in Wyckoff's sense as opposed to economies of scale conventionally defined. 71 John R. Meyer, Merton J. Peck, John Stenason and Charles Zwick, The Economics of Competition in the Transportation Industries (Cam- bridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1964), p. 211. 72 Nelson "Motor Freight Transport in New England..." 73 Roberts "Some Aspects of Motor Carrier Costs..." 110 74 Gary N. Dicer, "Economies of Scale and Motor Carrier Optimum Size," Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, (Spring, 1971), p. 32. ‘75 Paul l(. Sugrue, Manfred H. Ledford and Nicholas A. Glaskowsky, Jr., "Operating Economies of Scale in the U.S. Long Haul Common Carrier, Motor Freight Industry," Transportation Journal 22 (Fall 1982): 27-41 76 Ibid., p. 27. 77 Ibid., p. 30. 78 Ibid., p. 38. 79 Thomas Gale Moore, "Deregulating Surface Freight Transporta- tion," in Promoting Competition in Regulated Markets, ed. Almarin Phillips (Washington, D.C.: The BroOkings Institutibn, 1975), pp. 55-98. 80 Ibid. 31 U.S., Interstate Commerce Comission, Bureau of Economics, A Cost and Benefit Evaluation of Surface Transportation Regulation, (Washington, D.C.: 1976). PP. 6-7. 32 Jack Lamkin, "Organization and Competition in Transportation: The Agricultural Exempt Sector," Transportation Journal 13 (Fall 1973): 30-37. 83 Ibid., p. 31. 84 Ibid. 85 Ibid. 85 Ibid. 87 Ibid., p. 34. 88 Ibid., p. 35. 89 W. Miklius, K. L. Casavant and W. Huang, "Entry, Exit and Survival of Exempt Motor Carriers," Transportation Journallb (Fall 1976): 16-25. 90 Ibid., p. 15. 91 Ibid., p. 24. 92 James Sloss, "Regulation of Motor Freight Transportation: A Quantitative Evaluation of Policy," Bell Journal of Economics I (Autumn 1970): 327-66. 93 Ibid., p. 341. 111 94 Ibid. 95 Ibid. 96 Ibid., p. 347. 97 John Palmer, "A Further Analysis of Provincial Trucking Regulation," The Bell Journal Of Economics and Management Science 4 (Autumn 1973): 655764, as citedby David H. Maister, TRegulation and the Level of Trucking Rates in.-Canada: Additional Guidance," Trans- portation Journal 18 (Winter 1978): 49-62. 98 D. 1.. McLachlin, "Canadian Trucking Regulation," The Lpgistics and Transportation Review B (1972): 59-81, as cited in Maister, p. 49. 99 James Sloss, "The Regulation of Motor Freight Transport in Canada: A Reappraisal of Policy," a paper prepared for the Conference on Socioeconomic Experience Abroad, Cornell University, July 1975, as cited in Maister, p. 49. 100 W. Bruce Allen, Steven Lonergan, and David Plane, Examinations of the Unregulated Trucking Experience in New Jersey, prepared for the Research and Special Projects Administration, U.S. Dept. of Transporta- tion, Wash., D.C., 1978. 101 Ibid., pp. 2, 55. 10? Ibid., p. 179. 103 Ibid., p. 175. 104 Ibid. 105 Ibid., p. 178. 105 Ibid. 107 Ibid. 108 James C. Nelson, "The Economic Effects of Transport Deregula- tion in Australia," TranSportation Journal 16 (Winter 1976): 48-71. 109 Ibid., pp. 55-57. 110 U.S., Department of Transportation, Federal Railroad Admi- nistration, Office of Policy and Program Development, James R. Nelson, ed. Foreign Regulatory Experiments: Implications for U.S.: An Analysis and Evaluation of Foreign Regulatory Experience Report No. FRIF-OPPD- 77-24, (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1977, p. 3-66. 112 111 Temple, Barker, and Sloane, Inc. Transportation Strategies for the Ei hties A report prepared under contract to the National Council of Physical Distribution Management (Oakbrook, Ill.: NCPDM, 1982), p. 108. Temple, Barker and Sloane in turn cite Interstate Commerce Commission, Office of Policy and Analysis, The Effects of Recession on the Motor Carrier Industry, (June, 1981), pp. 2-3. 112 Dennis Breen, Regulatory Reform and the Truck Industry: An Evaluation of the Motor Carrier Act of T980, submitted to the Moior Carrier Ratemaklng Study Commission, March 1982, p. 27, as cited by Temple, Barker and Sloane, p.108. 113 Temple, Barker and Sloane, pp. 108-109. 114 Thomas M. Corsi, J. Michael Tuck, and Leland L. Gardner, "Minority Motor Carriers and the Motor Carrier Act of 1980," Trans- portation Journal 21 (Spring 1982): 22-23. 115 Ibid., pp. 54 and 52. 115 Thomas M. Corsi, J. Michael luck, and Leland L. Gardner, "Owner Operators and the Motor Carrier Act of 1980," Logistics and Trans- portation Review 18 (Sept. 1982): 255-77. 117 Ibid., p. 274. 118 Donald V. Harper, "Consequences of Reform of Federal Economic Regulation of the Motor Trucking Industry," Transportation Journal 21 (Summer 1982): 35-58. 119 Ibid., pp. 55-57. 120 Ibid. 121 Ibid. 122 Ibid., p. 57. 123 Ibid. 124 U.S., Interstate Commerce Commission, Office of Transportation Analysis, Highlights of Recent Activity in the Motor Carrier Industry, Staff Report No. VIII (WaShington D.C.: Interstate Commerce Com- miSsion, 1982). 125 Ibid., pp. 1-8. 126 Ibid., p. 8. 127 Ibid., p. 12. 128 Ibid. 129 Ibid., pp. 13-14. 113 130 U.S., General Accounting Office, The Household Goods Moving Industry: Changes Since Passage of Regulatory Reform Legislation (WashingtonlD.C.: U.S. General Accounting Office, 1983), pp. 15-392 131 Bryon Nupp, "The Common Carrier System in a Modern Econany -Research Problems," Transportation Journal 16 (Fall 1976): pp. 5-15. 132 Ibid., p. 5. 133 Dicer. 134 Ibid., p. 33. 135 Ibid. 135 Ibid., p. 34. 137 Ibid., pp. 34-35. 138 Ibid., p. 35. 139 Ibid. 140 Ibid., p. 37. 141 Rodger Koenker, "Optimal Scale and the Size Distribution of American Trucking Firms," Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 11 (January 1977): 54-67. 142 Ibid., p. 52. 143 Ibid., p. 55. 144 James P. Rakowski, "Motor Carrier Size and Profibflfilityg' Transportation Journal 16 (Summer 1977): 36-45. 145 Roberts, "Some Aspects of Motor Carrier Costs..." 145 Nelson, "Motor Freight Transport for New England..." 147 Meyer et. al., The Economics of Competition... 143 Edwin P. Patton, "Implication of Motor Carrier Growth and Size,"' Transportation Journal (Fall 1970) as cited in Rakowski, "Motor Carrier SiZe...,"‘p. 36. 149 Mark L. Ladenson and Alan J. Stoga, "Returns to Scale in the U.S. Trucking Industry," Southern Economic Journal (Jan. 1974), as cited in Rakowski, "Motor Carrier Size...,“ p. 36. 150 Paul W. Emery, "An Empirical Approach to Motor Carrier Economies of Scale," Land Economics (August 1965) as cited in Rakowski, "Motor Carrier Size...," p. 36. 114 151 Dicer. 152 Rakowski, "Motor Carrier Size...," p. 36. 153 Ibid., p. 43. 154 Ibid., p. 44. 155 James P. Rakowski, "Cost Differences According to Firm Size in U.S. Trucking," Transportation Journal 18 (Winter 1978): 63-70. 155 Ibid., p. 59. 157 Ibid. 158 Ibid. 159 Ibid., p. 70. 150 Dicer. 161 Wyckoff. 152 Rakowski, "Cost Differences...," p. 70. 153 T. H. Maze, "The Value of Information in Unregulated Truck Service Markets," Transportation Journal 20 (Winter 1980): 57-62. 164 Ibid., p. 52. 155 David H. Maister, "Regulation and the Level of Trucking Rates in Canada: Additional Guidance," Transportation Journal 18 (Winter 1978): 49-62. 155 Sloss. 157 David H. Maister, "Regulation and the Level of Trucking Rates in Canada," Motor Carrier Economic Regulation, proceedings of a workshop conducted by the Comllittee on Transportation, National Research Council (Washington D.C.: National Academy of Sciences, 1978), I”). 199-231 as cited in Maister, p. 49. 158 Ibid. 169 Maister in Transportation Journal, p. 53. 170 Ibid., p. 50. 171 Ibid., p. 51. 172 Garland Chow, "Studies of Intrastate Trucking Regulation - A Critique," Transportation Journal 19 (Summer 1980): p. 270. 173 Ibid., p. 210. 115 174 Ibid., p. 218. 175 Ibid., pp. 220-21. 175 James C. Nelson, "The Economic Effects of Transport Dere- gulation in Australia," Transportation Journal 16 (Winter 1976): p. 57. 177 Wilbrod LeClerc, "Competition in Canadian Freight Transporta- tion: A General Survey," Transportation Journal 19 (Spring 1980): p. 74. 178 Wyckoff. 179 U. S. Interstate Commerce Commission, Highlights of Recent Activity... 180 Ibid., p. 2. 181 Ibid., p. 8. 182 Ibid., p. 12. 183 Ibid., pp. 17-18. 184 Stigler, "The Theory...," p. 6. 185 Ibid., p. 8. 186 Ibid., p. 9. 187 Ibid. 133 Donald V. Harper and James C. Johnson, "The Shipper Views Deregulation of Transportation," I.C.C. Practitioners Journal 41 (March-April 1974): p. 319. 189 Ibid. 190 Donald V. Harper, "The Shipper Views Economic Regulation of For- Hire Trucking," I..C. C. Practitioners Journal (Oec.1963), as cited in Harper and Johnson, p. 320. 191 Robert A. Nelson, "Interest Conflicts in Transportation," Journal of Business (April 1964), as cited in Harper and Johnson, p. 320. 192 Harper and Johnson, pp. 331, 329. 193 Grant M. Davis, Charles S. Sherwood, and L. J. Rosenberg, "A Oichotomous Perception of Transportation Regulation - Deregulation, An Analysis," Logjstics and Transportation Review 12 (1976): 273-81. 194 Ibid., p. 274. 116 195 Ibid., p. 279. 195 James A. Constantin, Roger E. Jerman, and Ronald D. Anderson, "Rail, Motor, and Shipper Opinions on Regulatory Issues," Transportation Journal 17 (Fall 1977): 40-50. 197 Ibid., p. 42. 198 Ibid. 199 Roger E. Jerman, Ronald D. Anderson, and James A. Constantin, "Physical Distribution Management Views on Regulation Issues," Logistics and Transportation Review 13 (1977): 107-22. 200 Ibid., p. 109. 201 Ibid., p. 114. 202 Ibid., p. 115. 203 Charles G. Burck, "The Pros and Cons of Deregulating the Truckers," Fortune, June 1979, pp. 140-43. 204 Ibid., p. 140. 205 Ibid. 205 James R. Stock, "Regulations, Regulators, and Regulatory Issues: A Motor Carrier Perspective," Transportation Journal 18 (Spring 1979): 65-73. 207 Ibid., p. 59. 203 Ibid. 209 Thomas S. Ulen, "The Market for Regulation: The I.C.C. From 1887 to 1920," American Economic Review 70 (May 1980): 306-10. 210 Ibid., pp. 305-307. 211 Ibid., p. 309. 212 Ibid., p. 310. 213 Ibid. 214 Charles G. Stalon, "Trucking Regulations Within Illinois: Impressions of a New Commissioner," Transportation Journal 18 (Winter 1978): 43-48. 215 Ibid., p. 43. 215 Ibid., p. 47. 117 217 Robert C. Lieb, "Relaxing Motor Carrier Regulation: The Massachusetts Attempt," Logistics and Transportation Review 4 (1975): 193-201. 218 Ibid., p. 197. 219 Ibid., p. 199. 220 Stigler. 221 Harper and Johnson. 222 Constantin et. al. "Rail, Motor, and Shipper Opinions..." 223 Jerman et. al. "Physjcal Distribution Management Views..." 224 Burck, "The Pros and Cons..." 225 Stock. 225 Stalon. 227 Lieb. 223 Davis et. al., p. 279. ‘229 Constantin et. al., "Rail, Motor, and Shipper Opinions...," p. 42. 230 Ulen, p. 310. 231 Allen et. al., p. 178. 232 James A“ Constantin, Jack J. Kasulis, Robert F. Lusch and Paul H. Zinzer, "A Marketing Framework for a Motor Carrier of General Commodities," ProCeedings: Transportation Research Forum 19 (1978): 339-46. 233 Joseph A. Potter and Hi-Chi-Wang, "A Marketing Strategy Under Motor Carrier Deregulation," Proceedings: TranSportation Research Forum 20 (1979): 488-500. 234’Allan D. Schuster, "Motor Common Carrier Corporate Strategy in an Uncertain Regulatory Environment," Proceedings: Transportation Research Forum 20 (1979): 126-33. 235 Roger E. Jerman, Ronald D. Anderson, and James A. Constantin, "Motor Carrier Marketing: A Product Perspective," Proceedings: Transportation Research Forum 19 (1978): 347-55. 235 Warren Rose and David Zientara, "Market Segmentation: Key to New Business for Motor Carriers," in Contemporary Issues in Marketing Channels, eds. Robert F. Lusch and Paul H. Zinzer (Norman, Oklahoma: University of Oklahoma, 1979), pp. 157-63. 118 237 Fred C. Bauer, "Marketing Ramifications of the Motor Carrier Act of 1980," Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the National Council of Physical Distribution Ranagement (Chicago: NCPDM, 1980), pp. 357-66. 238 Frank H. Mossman and Gregory S. Maiers, "Creative Adjustment to Motor Carrier Deregulation," MSU Business Topics 28 (Autumn 1980): 51-56. 239 Sales and Marketing Council of the American Trucking Associ- ations, Marketing Management (Washington, D.C.: ATA, 1980). Inc., and A. T. Kearney Management Consultants, Motor Carrier 240 241 242 .243 244 245 246 247 248 Hunt et. al., p. 269. Constantin et. al., "A Marketing Framework...," p. 345. Potter and Wang, p. 494. Ibid. Schuster, p. 132. Rose and Zientara, p. 157. Mossman and Maiers, p. 51. Jerman et. al. "Motor Carrier Marketing...," p. 355. Robert A. Robicheaux, William L. James, and Earnest R. Cadotte, "Segmenting Common Motor Carrier Markets on the Basis of Customer Satisfaction," Proceedings: Transportation Research Forum 19 (1978): p. 333. 249 Ibid. 250 Ibid., p. 335. 251 Ibid., p. 337. 119 CHAPTER IV ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK AND RESEARCH DESIGN Introduction The general research questions treated by the study were: to determine the pricing behaviors of Class I and Class II regular route common carriers of general commodities; to determine whether those behaviors constituted a change since deregulation; and to determine whether it was possible to develop a taxonomy of those pricing be- haviors. Four specific research questions were adopted which reflected the assumption that pricing was becoming more competitive in the context of essential heterogeneity, and the data were examined for conformance with the expectations of the Stigler theory of economic regulation. Achievement of these research goals should provide insights into whether or not a carrier group, whose conformance with the competitive model had been questioned, is now behaving more im accordance with that model than it had prior to deregulation. The taxonomy development provides a detailed view of heterogeneous pricing behavior within the group. At the same time, the observation of pricing after a shift in regulatory environment provides the opportunity to observe changes in profitability, stated political positions and reported political behavior in the context of Stigler's expectations. The study is conducted in the context of some evidence of competitive entry, and in the context of the economic recovery of Fall, 1983. Research Framework As outlined briefly in chapter one, the research was conducted in five phases. First, a review of the literature was undertaken in order to identify the important issues or arguments surrounding motor carrier 120 deregulation and to identify specific research questions for the study. This resulted in the identification of the historical observations, debate issues, theoretical perspectives, and empirical evidence reviewed in chapters two and three, as well as the adoption of Specific research questions one through four. The second phase of the study was comprised of a reevaluation of the literature. This was undertaken in order to identify Specific observations or predictions which might be translated into questionnaire items to support a specific research question. These resulting items, together with open-ended questions, were then incor- porated in an interview guide which was used in the exploratory inter- views, the third component of the research and the first field com- ponent. The exploratory interviews were conducted using a convenience sample of carrier management, industry observers and transportation/ physical distribution management. The interviews were undertaken during June, 1983, and varied in format from a five hour one-on-one personal interview to a two hour telephone interview. In all cases, the inter- view guide was followed to the maximum extent allowed by the partici- pants' time, interest, and knowledge. Ten such interviews were com- pleted. The results of these exploratory interviews included: a narrowing and focusing of the research questions; a translation of the research questions into industry terms and activities; identification of pricing behaviors which had not been anticipated in the literature; and identification of potential classifications for a pricing taxonomy. The exploratory interviews were followed by a mail survey and follow-up (phase four) and data analysis (phase five). These two phases are now discussed in some detail. 121 Mail Survey: Instrument and Pretesting The survey instrument used in the research contained forty-five questions, some of which utilized subcategories requiring responses. A total of ninety-two responses were required in order to complete the questionnaire. The instrument was developed by forming questions concerning pricing behavior which: 1) were supportive of one of the specific research questions one through four, 2) provided the basis for a taxonomy development, or 3) examined relationships important to the Stigler theory. Inspiration for a specific question was derived from either the literature or the exploratory interviews. Following initial development of the questionnaire, the questions were restructured for efficiency and logical consistency and were presented to members of the dissertation committee for comment and adjustment. The questionnaire was then pretested using a judgment sample of carrier top management. Five presidents, three vice presidents, and one manager of sales and marketing representing seven different regular route common carriers of general comnodities participated. During this pretest, the questionnaire was personally administered, and the time required to complete the instrument was recorded. Executive suggestions concerning the wording of specific questions were considered and, in some cases, resulted in adjustments to the instrument. In general, the executives were cordial and interested in the study. Twenty minutes had been requested for the interview, but company presidents sometimes gave as much-as two and one-half hours to the pretest and discussion. A second pretest was then mailed to a random sample of ten carrier presidents derived from the American Trucking Association's listing of regular route common carriers of general commodities. Three usable responses were eventually received as a result of this mailing. 122 Following minor adjustments as a result of the pretest, the questionnaire was produced as a computer readable brochure and was mailed together with a cover letter and a stamped, self-addressed envelope. The questionnaire comprises Appendix A of this report, and the cover letter comprises Appendix 8. Sample and Sampling Method The questionnaire was mailed to a census of 732 regular route common carriers of general commodities. The census listing was developed using the American Trucking Association's carrier file list accessed on July 22, 1983. This file list is used by the American Trucking Association in developing the Executive and Ownership Report Class I and 11 Motor Carriers of Property. Study of the ownership report itself indicated that clerical errors had been made in its compilation. The American Trucking Association acknowledged the errors and allowed direct access to the carrier file in order to generate a more nearly error free list. All carriers listed as regular route common carriers of general commodities were included in the survey. Data Collection The questionnaires were mailed to the president of each firm on November 7, 1983. Each questionnaire was accompanied by an individually addressed business style cover letter which introduced the study, solicited help,land promised a summary of results upon request (see Appendix B). A stamped, self-addressed envelope was also enclosed. On November 28, 1983, a reminder letter was mailed. The reminder letter expressed appreciation to those who had already returned the question- naire and requested help from those who had not. The letter included the researcher's home telephone and address and suggested that those who 123 had misplaced the original questionnaire might write or call for another (see Appendix C). This second mailing resulted in several letters and telephone calls which requested that a new questionnaire be sent. These requests were generally cared for within a twenty-four hour period. On December 31, 1983, data collection was considered to be com- plete. By that date, the mailings had resulted in 204 responses (27.9%) of one kind or another from trucking executives. Four executives (.5%) had written to explain why it was their decision not to respond to the survey. Another five (.6%) had written to explain that their filun had gone out of business and some explained this in terms of pricing behaviors. Ten blank questionnaires were returned. In all, 185 (25.3%) completed or partially completed questionnaires were returned, some executives opting to avoid answering certain questions. As a partially completed questionnaire provided useful responses to many questions, these questionnaires were used. Non deliverables accounted for 68 (9.3%) of the original mailing. The response rates recalculated as. percentages of the effective sample (the sample originally selected minus non-deliverables) appear together with other response data as figure 4-1. Low response rates are a problem with any mail survey.1 These rates are considered acceptable, as returns of 40% or better may be considered to be exceptional, and returns of five to ten percent may be considered common in mail surveys.2 Data Analysis and the Purpose of the Research The overall purpose of the research as stated in Chapter One was to address the following general questions: 1. What is the current (fall, 1983) pricing behavior of Class I and Class II regular route common carriers of general commodities? 124 Figure 4-1 Mailings, Responses, and Response Rates Original List of Regular route Common Carriers of General Commodities ............ 742 names Pre-test Group ................. 10 names 3 responses October First Mailing .................. 732 names November 7 Non Deliverables ............... 68 names Effective Sample ............... 664 names Second Mailing ................. 732 names November 28 Responses, Useful Questionnaires [Respondents Avoiding Some Questions] ....... 185 Items By December 31 Responses, Informational Letters Other Than Questions... 9 Items By December 31 Blank Questionnaires Returned.. 10 Items By December 31 Total Responses ................ 204 Items By December 31 Total Responses 27.9% 30.7% [Includes Information Letters] As % of As % of Effective Total Mailing Sample (Total Mailing -Non Deliverables) Useful Questionnaires 25.3% 27.9% As % of As % of Effective Total Mailing Sample 2. How has this behavior changed since deregulation? 3. Is it possible to develop a taxonomy (classification) of such pricing behavior? A series of research questions was developed to achieve the stated purpose. The following section relates the data analysis involved with each research question to the purpose of the study. 125 The statement of Question 1A was, "To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by the use of contracts vs. tariffs?" This research question addresses the purpose of describing one major aspect of current pricing behavior of the carrier group. The question recognizes the heterogeneity arguments in the theoretical and applied literature and reflects the expectation that in a deregulated environ- ment, pricing will be individualized. The specific data analyses in support of Research Question 1A are treated below under the heading, "Data Analysis: Research Question 1A." The statement of Question 18 was, "Does carrier top management see this as constituting a change since deregulation?" This research question addresses the purpose of describing change in this specific aspect of carrier pricing behavior since deregulation. It reflects the expectation that change will be in the direction of more individualized pricing. For both Research Question 1A and 18, the research examines both contracts per se and independent tariff making behavior which often serves the individualizing function of contracting. The specific data analyses in support of Research Question 18 are treated below under the heading, "Data Analysis: Research Question 18." The statement of Question 2A was, "To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by extensive discounting?" This research question addresses the purpose of describing a second major aspect of the current pricing behavior of the carrier group. The question reflects the argument that the carriers in this previously profitable industry will react competitively to a deregulation and will engage in market entry and price discounting behavior upon the lessening of legal constraint. This question is particularly important for this carrier 126 group. The regular route comnon carriers of general commodities have been identified as having relatively high barriers to entry. It has been argued that they might not react to a deregulation with competitive behavior. The research examines both discounting interpreted as specific discounts and discounting interpreted as price reductions. The specific data analyses in support of Research Question 2A are treated below under the heading, "Data Analysis: Research Question 2A." The statement of Question 28 was, "Does carrier top management see this as constituting a change Since deregulation?" This question addresses the purpose of describing change in an aspect of carrier pricing behavior since the deregulation. It reflects the competitive expectation that discounting will have increased. This expectation is derived from the high profitability of the industry prior to deregula- tion, from the lessening of constraints upon entry and pricing, and from the arguments that the industry is structured competitively. The data analyses in support of Research Question 28 are described below under the heading, "Data Analysis: Research Question 28." The statement of Question 3A was, "To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by cross subsidies?" This research question addresses the purpose of describing a third major aspect of current pricing behavior within the carrier group. It reflects the arguments surrounding the welfare goals of the earlier tariff structure. The competitive expectation would be that cross subsidy could not be maintained. Any shipments carried at rates so substantially above costs as to allow cross subsidization of other shipments would logically be taken by competitors. Thus, any previous cross subsidy of rural or 127 small shipments can be expected to disappear with a deregulation iii the effects of the deregulation are competitive. The data analyses in support of Research Question 3A are described below under the heading, "Data Analysis: Research Question 3A." The statement of Question 38 was, "Does carrier management see this as constituting a change since deregulation?" This question addresses the purpose of describing change in this aspect of carrier pricing behavior since the deregulation. The competitive expectation would be that cross subsidy could not be sustained. Therefore, change is expected in the direction of the elimination of cross subsidy. Specific data analyses are described below under the heading, "Data Analysis: Research Question 38." The statement of Question 4A was, "To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by innovation? (innovative price/service combinations)." This question addresses the purpose of describing a fourth major aspect of current carrier pricing behavior. It reflects the arguments concerning the relationship of market structure to innovative propensity, and the perspective that regulation has inhibited innovation in this industry. The data analyses are described under the heading, "Data Analysis Research Question 4A." The statement of Question 48 was, "Does carrier top management see this as constituting a change since deregulation?" This question addresses the purpose of describing change in a fourth aspect of pricing behavior since the deregulation. It addresses the theoretical and applied arguments concerning the relationship of competition to inno- vation. The expectation would be that increased competition and increased freedom would result in increased innovation in any situation 128 short of extremely rigorous competition. The specific data analysis in support of this perspective are presented below under the heading, "Data Analysis Research Question 48." The taxonomy development procedures address the stated research purpose of determining whether it is possible to develop a taxonomy or classification of pricing behavior within this carrier group. Taxonomy development represents a first step in the scientific investigation of any phenomenon. In this case, it is also a useful device for the investigation of arguments concerning the heterogeneity of market behavior. Specific data analyses in support of taxonomy development are discussed below under the heading, "Data Analysis: Taxonomy Develop- ment." An additional goal of the research was to view the results in the context of the Stigler theory of economic regulation. This theoretical perspectivelwould hold in essence that the regulation had benefited the industry, protecting it from competition. Competitive findings in the major research questions would support this perspective, but other specific questions were asked. Findings that the firms were consis- tently opposed to the deregulation, and findings to the effect that firms had lost profitability were sought in support of the Stigler framework. The data analysis procedures are described below under the heading, "Data Analysis: The Stigler Perspective." The data analysis procedures undertaken are now outlined in detail. For each specific research question, the analytical framework is further specified by identifying the source of the data on the questionnaire (included as appendix A), the treatment of the data as ratio, interval, ordinal, or nominal, the goal of statistical inference, and the statis- 129 tical test or procedure used. The taxonomy development is approached using extensive cross tabulation. These cross tabulations and asso- ciated statistical procedures are also outlined in this section. The Stigler perspective is approached using a series of questionnaire items. The logic of these is set forth below, together with the goals of statistical inference, the treatment of the data, and the statistical tests used. Data Analysis: Research Question 1A Research question 1A was phrased as "to what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterizedby the use of contracts vs. tariffs?" The data for this analysis are derived from questionnaire item 35. Executives respond to this item by dividing 100% of their revenues into four Specified categories plus one open-ended category. Responses in the open-ended category may then be allocated to one of the first four specified groups. Data are summarized through a display depicting the number of carriers obtaining differing proportions of their revenue from the rate categories described (figure 4-2). This sumnary provides tabulations within category and allows identification of the modal category. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample distribution was derived from a population having a null distribution with equal proportions of contract vs. tariff revenue as categorized above. To this end, the original frequency distributions as outlined in figure 4-2 are consolidated and compared. The data in the revenue categories have an ordinal property and the Kolmogorov-Smirnov Goodness of Fit Test is used to compare the frequency distributions. 130 Figure 4-2 Frequency of Carriers In Revenue Categories % of Revenue 0-20 21 - 4O 41 - 60 61 - 80 81 - 100 Rate Type (A) Contracts (8) Special One or Few (C) Independent Large #5 (0) Bureau Tariffs (E) Other ————————————————— _—————_——————————— —————_——-————————1 _______._______.____1 Two such procedures are undertaken. The first procedure compares contracts legally defined (Rate Type A in figure 4-2) to a consoli- dation of all other categories (B-D where E may be assigned to another category). The second procedure compares contracts defined in terms of economic function (Types A and B) to a consolidation of other cate- gories. These data analysis procedures allow statements to be made con- cerning the extent of carrier use of contracts, special tariffs, independent tariff schedules and bureau tariffs. They also allow statements to be made concerning extent of the use of contracts versus tariffs. 131 Data Analysis: Research Question 18 Research question 18 was phrased: "Does carrier management see this (1A) as constituting a change since deregulation?" Data for this analysis are derived from the multiple choice component of question 35. Executives are asked to decide whether the percentage of revenue that they have just estimated is more, the same, or less than prior to deregulation. These responses are treated as nominal data and are summarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample response distribution was derived from a population distribution of equal proportions, and the x2 test will be used for this purpose. Each rate category (contracts, etc.) will be examined individually. A statement may then be made as to whether executives see the revenue proportions reported in research question ]J\ as constituting a change in each rate category. Data Analysis: Research Question 2A Research question 2A was phrased: "To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by extensive discounting?" This research question is approached in several different ways. To begin with, discounting may be interpreted as the offering of specific discounts, or as price cutting. Secondly, price cutting may be viewed in terms of deviation from bureau tariffs or in terms of the relationship of revenues to costs. Each of these perspectives is investigated. Discounting Interpreted as Specific Discounts The data for this analysis are derived from question 36, items A through N. Executives are asked to respond in the context of each named discount (A through N) as to whether they have started the activity 132 Since deregulation, are doing more, the same, less, have stepped the activity since deregulation, or have never engaged in the activity. Executive responses to these items are treated as nominal scale data and are summarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. For each named discount, respondents are categorized as engaging in or as not engaging in the discount. The goal of sta- tistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample response distribution (frequencies in cells) was derived from a population of equal proportions (engaging vs. not engaging). The X2 test is used. A statement may then be made as to the extent to which carrier pricing behavior is characterized by extensive discounting, where this is seen in terms of the frequency of carriers engaging in specific named discounts. Pricing Cutting: Deviation From Bureau Tariffs The data for this analysis are derived using questions 20, 21, 22, and 35. The first three questions are used to identify groups for which each type of rate considered (contracts, special tariffs, items, or schedules) are "always" or "usually" lower than bureau tariffs. These groups are displayed in figure 4-3. For each group so identified, the proportion of respondents is tabulated, and for each of these groups, figure 4-2 is reconstructed. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether each of these groups, taken individually, differs from the population as a whole in their use of these rate categories. The comparison is made in the format of figure 4-2 and a series of Kolmogorov Smirnov Two Sample Tests are used. These data analyses allow statements to be made concerning the extent of the identified group's use of these categories in comparison with that of the group as a whole. 133 Figure 4-3 Identification of Groups Using Rate Categories As Price Cutting Mechanisms Always Lower Usually Lower Than Bureau Than Bureau (A) Contracts Group A Group B (8) Special Tariffs or Items Group C Group D (C) Independent Schedules Group E Group F Price Cutting: Relationship of Revenue to Costs Data for this analysis are derived from questions 23 and 24. Each question is analyzed separately, but the analytical procedures are identical. Question 23 is used to determine, for the carrier respond- ing, what % of traffic as measured by S revenue is accounted for by situations where rates are "extremely close to costsc" Question 24 identifies the same percentage for the traffic which is "actually losing money." The frequency of executive selection of percentage categories is treated as nominal data and is summarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample distribution was derived from a population having the null distribution of equal proportions. The X2 test is used. A statement may then be made concerning the frequency of carriers experiencing price-cost combinations such that given percentages of their revenue fall into the break even (question 23) or losing (Question 24) category. 134 Data Analysis: Research Question 28 Research question 28 was phrased: "Does top management see this (extent of discounting 2A) as constituting a change since deregulation?" The data analysis to determine whether change is reported is also divided according to whether discounting is interpreted as specific discounts or as price cutting. Price cutting is again treated in terms of deviation from bureau tariffs and in terms of the relationship of revenues to costs. 28: Discounting as Specific Discounts The data for this analysis are derived from question 36. In this case, columns 1 and 2 are consolidated to form a grouping such that change amounts to "more" use of the discount. Columns 3 and 6 are consolidated to form a grouping such that there is "no change" reported, and columns 4 and 5 are consolidated into a grouping reporting that change amounted to "less" use of the discount. These data are treated as nominal data and summarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample response distribution was derived from a population distribution of equal proportions. The X2 One Sample Test is used. A statement may then be made as to whether executives report a change for each specific discount con- sidered. 28 Discounting as Price Cuttipg: Deviation from Bureau Tariffs Data for this analysis are derived from questions 20, 21, 22, and 35. The first three questions are again used to identify several groups for which contracts, special tariffs, items, and schedules are "always" or "usually" a lower rate than a bureau tariff. These groups have been 135 identified in figure 4-3. For each group, data are derived from the multiple choice component of question 35. These estimates of change are treated as nominal data and are sumnarized by tabulation with category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal Of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample response distri- bution was derived from a population distribution of equal prOportions- The X2 Test is used and each group is tested individually. A statement may then be made as to whether the groups using contracts, special tariffs, items, and schedules to cut price report the extent of their use of these rate mechanisms to constitute a change. 28 Discounting as Price Cutting: Relationship of Revenues to Costs Data for this analysis are derived from question 28. Question 28 requires that carriers select whether prices since deregulation are "closer to our costs" or "no closer to our costs." These responses are treated as nominal dichotomous data and are summarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample result was derived from a population with the null distribution of equal proportions (50:50). . The X2 Test with continuity correction will be used, allowing a statement to be made as to whether executives report a change. 28 Change Where Price Cutting is Seen as Either Specific Discounts or Price Reduction Question 26 is used to determine whether the group sees their prices as being lower, about the same, or higher than a year ago. The data are treated as nominal and are summarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample. 136 response distribution was derived from a population distribution of equal proportions. The X2 Test is used, allowing a statement to be made as to whether executives see their prices as lower, about the same, or higher than one year ago. Data Analysis: Research Question 3A Research question 3A was phrased: "To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by'the use of cross subsidies?" Cross subsidy exists when some shipments are carried at a loss while others are carried at a profit, the profitable Shipments thus "cross subsi- dizing" the unprofitable shipments. The extent of cross subsidy is approached using question 24, which asks that executives estimate the percentage of their traffic, as measured by S revenue, that they are actually losing money on. The resulting data are nominal and are summarized by tabulation with category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the observed distribution was derived from a population distribution of equal proportions in the revenue categories utilized. A X2 test is used. Statements may then be made concerning the current extent of cross subsidy as measured by the proportion of carriers involved in the cross subsidization of shipments amounting to different percentages of their revenues. Data Analysis: Research Question 38 Research question 38 was phrased: "Does carrier management see this (extent 3A) as constituting a change since deregulation?" The data for this analysis are derived from question 25. Executives are asked to estimate whether the extent of cross subsidy (their response to question 24) is more than, the same as, or less than before deregulation. The resulting data are treated as nominal and are sumnarized by tabulation 137 within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample distribution was derived from a population distribution of equal proportions. The X2 test is used, allowing a statement as to whether executives report a change. Several questions are designed to complement research questions 3A and 38 by examining the "nature" of cross subsidy and change in nature of cross subsidy as opposed to "extent" of cross subsidy. These questions are summarized in figure 4-4 below. The questions summarized in figure 4-4 yield nominal dichotomous data and are sumnarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the observed sample proportion is derived from a population with the null proportion of 50:50. The x2 test with continuity correction is used and allows a series of conclusions to be made concerning carrier agreement with the individual statements. Data Analysis: ResearchyQuestion 4A Research Question 4A was phrased: "To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by innovation (innovative price-service combinations)?" Data for this analysis are derived from Question 37 items A-Z. Executives are asked to respond in the context of each named innovation (A through Z) as to whether they have started the activity since deregulation, are doing more, the same, less, have stopped the activity since deregulation, or have never engaged in the activity. For each named innovation, respondents are then categorized as participating in the innovation or as not participating. Executive responses to these items are treated as nominal scale data and are summarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of 138 Figure 4-4 Questions Regarding the Nature of Cross Subsidy Question 11 Do carriers agree that they were forced to carry small LTL, rural service, etc. at a loss prior to deregulation? Question 12 Do carriers agree that items which they lost on prior to deregulation are still losing? Question 13 Do carriers agree that increased competition has made it difficult to make up a loss on one shipment by getting increased rates on another? Questhn114 Do carriers agree that there has been a change in the shipments they lose money on and make money on? Question 17 Do carriers agree that powerful shippers are now causing & some of their shipments to be carried at a loss (Q-17) 18 or very nearly so (Q-18)? Questth19 Do carriers agree that a trucking firm has to have a balance of business from "other" shippers so as to be able to afford to do business with more powerful shippers? statistical inference is to determine for each innovation, whether it is probable that the sample response distribution (frequencies in cells) was derived from a population of equal proportions (participating vs. not participating). The X2 test is used for this purpose. This allows a statement to be made concerning the extent to which the pricing behavior of this carrier group is characterized by each price service innovation, where "extent" is seen in terms of the number of carriers engaging in Specific named innovations. Data Analysis: Research Question 48 Research question 48 was phrased: "Does carrier top management see this (extent,4A) as constituting a change since deregulation?" The data are derived from question 37 items A through Z. For this analysis, columns 1 and 2 are consolidated (change=more), columns 3 and 6 are 139 consolidated (no change), and columns 4 and 55 are consolidated (change=less). The resulting data, frequencies in cells, are treated as nominal scale data and are summarized by tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the sample response distri- bution was derived from a population distribution of equal proportions. The X2 test is used, allowing a statement as to whether top management reports a change in the use of specific innovations since deregulation. Data Analysis: TaxonomyDevelopment The purpose of data analysis for taxonomy development is to determine whether pricing "types" can be identified and characterized within this motor carrier group. Extensive cross tabulation of data is undertaken, using questions which differentiate between candidate pricing types as determined in the exploratory research. The question group to be used this way is identified in figure 4-5. These questions will be used to cross tabulate all other responses. Beyond these price specific taxonomy questions other cross tabu- lations will be undertaken to facilitate taxonomy development. These include the following: 1. Responses to change items in the multiple choice component of Question 35 will be cross tabulated by all other responses to see if there are relationships between these changes and other characteristics of the firm. 2. Responses to use of specific discounts in question 36 will be cross tabulated by the dichotomous classification used in research question 2A (most revenue from contracts vs. most revenue from tariffs) in order to examine similarities between tariff behavior and discounting behavior. 140 Figure 4-5 Pricing Taxonomy Questions Question Identifies Candidate Type B Predator if true 10 Price leader if true 6 Cherry picker or shipment targeter if true 2 S.B.U. (strategic business unit) if true 19 Cream skimmer if true 20, 21,22 Premium vendor if responding rarely or never lower to all 3 29 Resistor if responds most 30 Price aggressor if responds true 3. The groups identified as using contracts, special tariffs, items and schedules which are "always" or "usually" lower than bureau tariffs (questions 20, 21, and 22 under research question 2A) are compared with respondents not falling into these groups along the axes of size and profitability. Appropriate statistical tests are applied to determine whether these candidate classifications differ along the other dimensions Specified (comparing 2 sets of responses from 2 independent groups). In general, T/F responses and multiple choice items utilize x2 tests, unless the multiple choice item has an ordinal property. In that case, the Kolmogorov-Smirnov 2 Group Test is used. Executive estimates of operating ratios, revenue and percentages would require the independent group t test for means, a procedure for the comparison of proportions or the X2 test for responses which are categorized. Following this 141 analysis, a statement may be made as to whether the research has identified pricing behavior groups which differ along any of the axes examined. Data Analysis: The Stigler Perspective The goal of the final data analysis is to determine whether the data gathered conform with the idea that regulation is sought by a group of firms for their own protection. This idea would be most strongly supported by the data pattern presented in figure 4-6. Within this group, questions 7, 15, and 33 yield nominal dichot- omous data. These are summarized using tabulation within category, modal category, or graphic display. The goal of statistical inference is to determine whether the sample result is likely to have been derived from a population with the null proportion of 50:50. The x2 test with continuity correction is used for this inference. Questions 31 and 32 yield ordinal data and are also sumnarized by tabulation within cate- gory, modal category, or graphic display. Here the goal of statistical inference is to determine whether the sample result is likely to have been derived from a population having the null distribution of equal proportions, and the Kolmogorov-Smirnov Goodness of Fit Test is used. Finally, a comparison of question 31 and 32 is undertaken, where the goal of statistical inference is to determine whether it is probable that the two sample distributions are derived from the same population distribution. A Kolmogorov-Smirnov test is also used here. Following these procedures, a statement can be made as to whether the data support the Stigler perspective. Data Processing The data were processed in the following manner. Incoming ques- tionnaires were inspected for usefulness and minor adjustments were made 142 Figure 4-6 Data Pattern Supporting The Stigler Perspective Q-7 Before deregulation supported efforts to stop it (T) Q-15 Now support efforts to roll back or slow dereg (T) Q-31 (strongly against) deregulation before Q-32 (strongly against) deregulation now Q-33 More profitable (before deregulation) No difference between 31 and 32 (No change in the direction of adjustment to the new status qua) to make the questionnaires ready for optical scanning. These adjust- ments included numbering the two pages of the questionnaire with a respondent number to allow identification of individual responses when the pages became separated, marking over respondents' answers with a number 2 pencil when respondents ignored the request that they use a soft lead No. 2 pencil, and repairing with tape any questionnaire which had been stapled or otherwise mutilated. When the questionnaires were ready for Optical scanning, they were taken to Michigan State University for reading, conversion to a tape for storage, and to allow the creation of an SPSS (statistical package for the social scienceS)3 data file. The SPSS program was created at Aquinas College where a second data file was created. The data file eventually used to develop the analyses presented in Chapter Six was the Aquinas College data file. The Michigan State data file was used to develop frequency runs to cross check the accuracy of the Aquinas data. The data manipulations were performed on the Aquinas 143 data file using the CDC computer at Michigan State University. This was accomplished by using a computer network system consisting of computers at Aquinas College, the University of Michigan, and Michigan State University. 144 Footnotes 1 David J. Luck, Hugh G. Wales, Donald A. Taylor and Ronald S. Rubin, Marketing Research, 6th ed. (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1982i 0. 115. 2 Walter B. Wentz, Marketing Research: Management and Methods (New York: Harper and Row, 1972), p. 83. 1 William R. Klecka, Norman H. Nie, and C. Hadlai Hull, Statistical Package for the Social Sciences Primer (New York: McGraw Hill, 1975). 145 CHAPTER V SUMMARY OF MAJOR FINDINGS Introduction This chapter provides a summary of the findings. These are pre- sented in the context of each research question or perspective. This is then followed by a set of conclusions which may be derived'hRMlthe findings. The next chapter provides supporting statistical detail while the implications of the findings comprise Chapter Seven, the last chapter of this report. To What Extent is Carrier Pricing Behavior Characterized By the Use of Contracts Vs. Tariffs? Substantial numbers of carriers were found to be deriving large percentages of their revenues from tariffs. Comparison of carrier use of contracts vs. tariffs allowed the following sumnary statement to be made: 1. As measured by the percentage of each firm's revenue accounted for, and regardless of whether special tariffs or special items aimed at one or a few shippers are considered to function as contracts, regular route common carriers of general commodities are now making greater use of tariffs than of contracts. Does Carrier Management See This (Extent of the Use of Tariffs vs. Contracts) as COnstituting a Change Since Deregulation? Each rate category used in this study was considered separately. Carriers reported increases in the use of special tariffs or special items aimed at one or a few shippers and increases in their use of independently published tariff schedules which were aimed at a large number of shippers. They were split as to whether contracts constituted more or less (revenue as a percentage) than prior to deregulaticnl and a 146 large number (57%) of the carriers reported making less use of bureau tariffs. These findings were summarized as follows: 1. The majority of the carrier group reported that their contract activity was greater than or equal to that prior to deregulation. 2. Carrier group behavior with respect to whether they arelnaking more or the same use of contracts does not differ significantly from the null hypothesis of equal proportions. 3. Since deregulation, the majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities are making greater use of special tariffs or special items which are aimed at one or a few shippers. 4. Since deregulation, the majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities are making greater use of independently pub- lished tariff schedules aimed at a large number of shippers. 5. When asked whether the percentage of revenue accounted for by bureau tariffs was more, the same, or less than before deregulation, the largest single group of regular route comnon carriers of general comnodities reports making less use of bureau tariffs. But, this group is not significantly larger than the combination of the groups which are making either the same use or more use of bureau tariffs. (Bureau tariffs here do not include independent actions which result in a special tariff, item, or schedule of independent tariffs.) To What Extent is Carrier Pricing Behavior Characterized By Extensive Discounting? Discounting was examined in terms of the use of specific named discounts, and in terms of price cutting. Price cutting, in turn, was examined in terms of deviation from bureau tariffs and in terms of the relationship of revenues to costs. The following statements were made as a result of these analyses: 147 Specific Discounts 1. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities are d . b. d. e. The are a. d. engaging in: Aggregate discounts Across the board percentage discounts Discounts for transport to and from certain areas or along certain routes Individually negotiated discounts Discounts calculated as percentages off of bureau tariffs majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities not engaging in: Discounts for late delivery based on the day of delivery Discounts for time of day of delivery and/or pickup Rebates or refunds after a shipper has purchased a certain amount Discounts calculated as a percentage of an independent tariff Carrier behavior with respect to the following discounts does not differ substantially from the null hypothesis of equal proportions (half engaging, half not): a. Discounts fOr multiple LTL shipments measured by tonnage within a time period Discounts based on total shipments measured by tonnage within a time period Discounts based on total shipments measured by dollar revenue within a time period Discounts for customer transport to and from the terminal Discounts for continuous movement, combined moves, and/or backhaul 148 Deviation from Bureau Tariffs l. Substantial numbers of carriers are utilizing contracts, special tariffs or items, and independently published tariff schedules to offer rates which are either always or usually lower than the bureau tariffs that would ordinarily apply to the traffic. (These fre- quencies are detailed in Figure 6-9.) Carriers using these rate categories for this purpose are not making any more or any less use of these categories than the carrier group as a whole. The majority of carriers use contracts to Offer a ratelnnch is "always" or "usually" lower than the bureau tariff that would ordinarily apply to the traffic. The majority of carriers use special tariffs or special items to offer a rate which is "always" or "usually" lower than the bureau tariff that would ordinarily apply to the traffic. The majority of carriers use schedules of independent tariffs to offer a rate which is "always" or "usually" lower than the bureau tariff that would ordinarily apply to the traffic. The majbrity of carriers are offering discounts calculated as a percentage off a bureau tariff. Relationship of Revenues to Costs 1. The majority Of regular route common carriers of general commodities report their rates to be extremely close to their costs for traffic amounting to 50% or more of their revenue. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities report actually losing money on traffic amounting to less than 25% of revenue. 149 Does Top Management See This (Extent of Discounting) as Constituting a Change Since DeregulatiONT Change in discounting behavior was examined in the same way that extentcnidiscounting had been. Specific discounts, deviation from bureau tariffs, and the revenue cost relationship were examined. One question asked about change in the absolute level of price Since last year. The results of these analyses were summarized as follows: Specific Discounts 1. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities report no change in their use of the following discounts since deregulation: a. Multiple LTL Shipments measured by tonnage b. Total shipments measured by tonnage C. Total shipments measured by dollar revenue d. Day of delivery e. Time of day of delivery f. Customer transport to and from the terminal 9. Continuous movement, combined moves, and/or backhaul h. Rebates or refunds after a shipper has purchased a certain amount i. Discounts calculated as a percent of an independent tariff 2. Of those reporting no change (use of the same amount, or never having used the discount), the modal category was in all cases "never" having made use of the discount. 3. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities report change in their use of the following discounts Since deregu- lation: 150 a. Tendering a minimum number of LTL shipments to be shipped at one time b. Across the board percentage discounts c. Individually negotiated discounts d. Discounts calculated as a percentage off a bureau tariff Of those reporting change (more use or less use), the modal category was in all cases making "more" use of the discount. Carrier behavior does not differ from the null hypothesis of equal proportions (half reporting change, half not) with respect to transport to and from certain areas and along certain routes. Deviation from Bureau Tariffs 1. The groups using contracts as a vehicle to cut price do not differ substantially from the group as a whole with respect to change in the use of contracts since deregulation. The groups using special tariffs and special items to cut price do not differ substantially from the group as a whole with respect to change in the use of special tariffs and special items since deregulation. The groups using schedules of independent tariffs as vehicles to cut price do not differ substantially from the group as a whole with respect to change in the use of schedules of independent tariffs since deregulation. Relationship of Revenues to Costs 1. Since deregulation the majority of regular route common carriers of general comodities have experienced changes in their revenue-cost relationships such that prices are now closer to costs. 151 Chapge in Price Level 1. Among regular route common carriers of general commodities, the group reporting lower prices since one year ago constitutes the largest single group, but it is not significantly larger than the combination of the groups reporting prices to be either about the same or higher than one year ago. To What Extent is Carrier Pricing Behavior Characterized. Bythe Use of Cross SUbsidieS? The study examined both extent and nature of cross subsidy. Extent was operationalized by accepting the definition that cross subsidy exists when some shipments are carried at a loss while others are carried at a profit, the profitable shipments thus making funds avail- able so as to allow the carriage of unprofitable shipments. Thus, executive estimates of the percentage of traffic they were actually losing on provided a measure of the "extent" of cross subsidy. The following summary statements were derived: 1. Carriers vary considerably as to the percentage of traffic as measured by dollar revenue which they report as actually losing money. 2. Where cross subsidy is measured as the percentage of traffic that is losing money and must therefore be cross subsidized by traffic which is making money, the majority of carriers are engaging in some cross subsidy. Does Carrier Management See This (Extent of Cross Subsidy) as Consti- tuting a Change Since Deregulation? The following statement summarizes the findings with respect to change in the extent of cross subsidy: 152 Where cross subsidy is measured as the percentage of traffic which is losing money and must, therefore, be cross subsidized by traffic which is making money, the majority of carriers report an increase in this percentage since deregulation. Supplementary Findings: Nature of Cross Subsidy As the extent of cross subsidy as measured in this study might be expected to increase as a function of general or across the board price declines, and as many of the arguments surrounding the deregulathnl centered upon the nature, rather than the extent of cross subsidy, several findings were derived concerning the nature and change in the nature of cross subsidy: 1. The majority of carriers agree that they were forced to carry some shipments (such as small LTL, rural service, etc.) at a loss prior to deregulation. The majority of carriers agree that they still lose on those Shipments which they lost on prior to deregulation. The majority of carriers agree that increased competition has made it difficult to make up a loss on one shipment by getting increased rates on another. The majority of carriers agree that the Shipments they lose money on and the shipments they make money on have changed since deregula- tion. The majority of carriers agree that powerful shippers are now causing some of their shipments to be carried at a loss. The majority of carriers agree that powerful shippers are now negotiating the prices on their traffic down closer to the carriers costs than other shippers have been able to do. 7. 153 The majority of carriers agree that a trucking firm now has to have a balance of business from "other" shippers in order to be able to afford to do business with more powerful shippers. To What Extent Has Carrier Pricing Behavior Been Characterized by Innovation (Innovative Price-Service COmbinationS)?l 1. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities were found to be engaging in the following innovations (0(= .05): a. The are Developing detailed knowledge of competition and their rates/- services Using road drivers to make "peddle" deliveries Using non-union drivers Buying larger trailers or trailer combinations Pricing after a complete market analysis including 1) study of customer needs, 2) study of competition, and 3) study of costs Taking the lead in suggesting price/service innovation to customers Offering overnight delivery Offering service at night and on weekends Adding service to new geographic areas Freight all kinds (F.A.K.) pricing majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities not engaging in the following innovations (O<= .05): Allowing marketing people to have final pricing authority Using computer models to look at marketing/operational options Allowing sales people to have pricing authority Formula pricing (any specific Shipment can be billed to an account using that account's formula) 154 e. In-depth logistical analysis of a shipper's distribution system (at carrier expense) f. Vending logistical analysis to a shipper (at his expense) 9. Using air freight connections Carrier behavior with respect to the following innovations does not differ significantly from the null hypothesis of equal proportions (half engaging, half not) (a<= .05): a. Using detailed shipment reports provided by the Shipper to cost out service to that shipper b.) Hiring people with logistics backgrounds for sales work c. Using non-union terminal workers d. Using special commodity divisions e. Zip code pricing f. Use of trip leases with owner operators 9. Cutting service back in some geOgraphic areas h. Using piggyback (TOFC) for line haul i. Shipping containerized freight Does Carrier Management See This (Extent of Innovation) as Constituting a Change Since Deregulation? 1. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities report no change in their use of the following "innovative" be- haviors since deregulation (os= .05): a. Using detailed shipment reports (provided by the shipper) to cost out service to that shipper b. Hiring people with logistical backgrounds for sales work c. Allowing marketing people to have final pricing authority d. Using computer models to look at marketing/operational options e. Allowing sales people to have pricing authority 155 f. Using non-union drivers 9. Using non-union terminal workers h. Using Special commodity divisions i. Use of trip leases with owner operators j. Formula pricing (any Specific shipment can be billed to an account using that account's formula) k. In-depth logistical analysis of a shipper's distributicnl system at carrier expense l. Vending logistical analysis (at shipper expense) m. Offering overnight delivery n. Offering service at night and on weekends 0. Cutting service back in some geographic areas p. Using piggyback (T.0.F.C.) for line haul q. Using air freight connections r. Shipping containerized freight Reports of no change included reports of engaging in the same amount and reports of never having engaged in the activity. With the exception of items m. and n., overnight delivery and service at night and on weekends, the modal category in each case of no change was never having made use of the innovation. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities report change in their use of the following innovations since deregulation (tx= .05): a. DevelOping detailed knowledge of competitors and their rates and services b. Pricing after a complete market analysis, including 1) study of customer needs, 2) study of competition, and 3) study of our COStS 156 c. Adding service to new geOgraphic areas Of those reporting change (more use or less use), the modal category was in all cases making "more" use of the innovation. Carrier behavior with respect to change in the use of the following innovations does not differ significantly from the null hypothesis of equal proportions (half reporting change, half not). a. Road drivers making peddle deliveries b. Buying larger trailers/combinations c. Zip code pricing d. Taking the lead in suggesting innovation e. Freight all kinds (F.A.K.) pricing Taxonomy Development A clean and complete taxonomy was not developed as clean mutually exclusive pricing types were not found. The following major findings emerged. 1. Carrier pricing behavior is substantially heterogeneous. 2. While mutually exclusive categories have not been found, categories have been found such that members of certain categories are unlikely to fall into certain of the other identified categories. 3. A pattern of price-cost behavior has been associated with each category which differentiates members of that category from non- members. The Stigler Perspective The following findings were obtained: 1. The majority of carriers reported that they had supported efforts to stop the deregulation prior to its passage. 2. The majority of carriers reported that they now support efforts to roll back or slow the advance of deregulation. 157 3. The majority of carriers were against the deregulation prior to its. passage. 4. The majority of carriers are still against the deregulation now. 5. The majority of carriers report that their firm was more profitable before the deregulation. 6. The distribution of carriers for and against the deregulation does not differ significantly when the pre-deregulation situation (Item 3 above) and the post-deregulation situation (Item 4 above) are compared. 7. The distribution of carriers supporting vs. not supporting political efforts against the deregulation does differ significantly when the pre-deregulation situation (Item 1 above) and the post-deregulation situation are compared. There is less support for such political activity in the post-deregulation period. Conclusions The following conclusions may be derived from the major findings summarized in this chapter and detailed in the following chapter. First, this carrier group is not abandoning tariff style rate-making in favor of contracts, rather it prefers to individualize rate-making through the publication of special tariffs or special items aimed at one or a few shippers. The group is also moving toward the use of indepen- dently published tariff schedules aimed at a large number of shippers. Bureau tariffs which do not fall into one of these categories still account'for a major portion of some carriers revenue, and remain an important pricing focal point, as much discounting is accomplished by calculating the discount as a percentage off of a bureau tariff. Many special tariffs, items and discounts are individually negotiated and aggregate discounts and discounts for transport to and 158 from certain areas and along certain routes are popular. When con- tracts, Special tariffs and items, or independently published tariff schedules are introduced to the marketplace, they generally represent rateSiHfich are lower than the bureau tariffs that would ordinarily apply to the traffic. No carriers were found that were systematically able to vend a substantial portion Of their traffic at rates above the bureau tariff structure. Discounting is extensive, with the majority of carriers reporting rates extremely close to costs for 50% or more of their revenue. The carrier group does not appear to be in real danger, however, as the majority of carriers are actually losing money on traffic which amounts to less than 25% of its revenue, and only 25 (14.5%) of the 185 carriers responding to the survey reported 1983 year to date operating ratios of over 100% (these data appear as Figure 5-1). This is hlspite of the deregulation having its predicted effect of changing the carriers revenue cost relationships so as to bring prices Closer to costs. Figure 5-1 Carrier Operating Ratios Q. 42 Approximately what is your 1983 year to date operating ratio? Under 90% 90-100% Over 100% 23 124 25 (13.4%) (72.1%) (14.5%) x2 not calculated on open ended questions. The changed environment provided by the administrative deregulation and the motor carrier act of 1980 does not appear to have been suffi- cient to have completely removed the previous cross subsidy of such 159 traffic as rural service and small LTL shipments, but crosssubsidi- zation has been made more difficult by increased competition for the more profitable shipments. While not entirely removing the old cross subsidy, the act seems to have provided an environment wherein a new form of cross subsidy may be developing. Carriers report that powerful shippers are able to negotiate rates on their traffic down closer to the carriers costs than other shippers have been able to do, that powerful shippers are now causing some of their shipments to be carried at a loss and that, in order to be able to afford to do business with powerful shippers, a trucking firm has to have a balance of business from other shippers in order to make up the profit. The group as a whole has not become substantially more innovative since the deregulation. Although the majority reported participating in several of what have been seen as major carrier industry innovations, few of these behaviors constituted a change since deregulation for the majority of reporting carriers. The innovations which were reported as change by the majority of carriers appear to be important. They were: 1. Developing detailed knowledge of competitors and their rates and services 2. Pricing after a complete market analysis, including 1) study of customer needs, 2) study of competition, and 3) study of our costs 3. Adding service to new geographic areas The first two appear important because they may be seen as incor- porating the essence of the marketing as "matching" approach. The third is important because it demonstrates a mode of market entry through whicfll competition may be increased in individual transportation markets without the creation of entirely new carriers. This survey was not able 160 to document substantial entry by new carriers. Only two (1.1%) of the respondent firms reported that their trucking firm was new and did not exist prior to the deregulation (Figure 5-2). Figure 5-2 New Firms Since Deregulation as Reported by Carrier Management Q. 1 Our trucking firm is new, it did not exist prior to deregulation T F 2 180 ( 1.1%) (98.9%) 172.12 x2 with continuity correction Significant at .05 1 Of The attempt to develop a pricing taxonomy provided useful insights into the substantially heterogeneous pricing behavior of the carrier group. Mutually exclusive categories were not found, but useful pricing behavior patterns were found, some of which were associated with greater or lesser profitability. The study also found substantial support for the perspective which holds that regulation is often sought by a regulated industry for its own protection, a perspective formalized by George Stigler. The carriers report that they supported efforts to stop the deregulation both before and after its passage. They were before and remain opposed to the deregulation and report that they were more profitable before the deregulation. One mitigating observation may be that there has been some small Shift of political support away from the anti-deregulation efforts. This might be interpreted as signifying carrier acknowledge- ment that they have lost this particular battle. 161 Detailed Analysis of Data and Implications A detailed analysis of data leading to these findings is presented in Chapter Six. The implications of the major findings of this study, as summarized in this chapter and as detailed in Chapter Six, together with the implications of selected minor findings of the study, comprise the final chapter of this report. 162 CHAPTER VI DETAILED ANALYSIS OF DATA AND RESULTS Introduction This chapter presents the detailed results of the data analysis procedures which were described in Chapter Four. These results have been summarized in Chapter Five. The data are presented in the context of specific research questions or perspectives, and are presented in the same order as they appeared in the previous chapter. Analysis of Data and Result: Research Question 1A Research Question 1A was phrased: "To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by the use of contracts vs. tariffs?" Pertinent data are displayed in Figure 6-1, a display depicting the number of carriers obtaining differing proportions of their revenue from the rate categories described. The~frequency distributions depicted in Figure 6-1 were consoli- dated and compared using the Kolmogorov-Smirnov Goodness of Fit Test. Figure 6-1 Frequency of Carriers in Revenue Categories % of Revenue Rate Type 0-20 21-40 41-60 61-80 81-100 (A) Contracts 151 7 4 1 2 (8) Special One or Few 85 47 22 7 4 (C) Independent Large #5 101 30 16 7 11 (0) Bureau Tariffs 52 3O 34 28 21 Responses in Rate Type E (other) are described in Appendix D ‘ 163 In the first such procedure, contracts legally defined (Rate Type A) were compared with a consolidation of all other categories (B-D). Category E (other) was not included in this procedure. The data thus consolidated appear as Figure 6-2. Figure 6-2 Contracts Legally Defined Compared to Tariffs Legally Defined Rate Category E Not Allocated 0-20 21-40 41-60 61-80 81-100 Contracts 151 7 4 1 2 (A) (91.5%) (4.2%) (2.4%) ( .6%) ( 1.2%) Tariffs 1 2 9 16 137 (B, C, D) ( .6%) (1.2%) (5.5%) (9.7%) (83.0%) A one group KS Goodness of Fit Test was used to compare the observed contract distribution to a hypothesized distribution equivalent to the tariff distribution. (Calculated value of D=.939, critical value of D (o<= .05 2 tailed test) = .106 In the second such procedure, contracts defined in terms of economic function (rate types A and B) were compared to a consolidation of the other tariff categories (C and D). The data consolidated in this way appear as Figure 6-3. Responses falling into rate Category E (other) were then evaluated. A summary Of this evaluation comprises Appendix 0. Due to the large number of carriers reporting no revenue in this category and due to the lack of a distinct pattern in the responses of those reporting revenue in the category, Category E was dropped from further consideration in the study. 164 Figure 6-3 Contracts Economically Defined Compared to Tariffs Rate Category E Not Allocated 0-20 21-40 41-60 61-80 81-100 Contracts 72 49 24 11 9 (A & B) (43.6%) (29.6%) (14.5%) ( 6.7%) ( 5.4%) Tariffs 13 15 34 51 52 (C & D) ( 7.8%) ( 9.1%) (20.6%) (30.9%) (31.5%) A one group KS Goodness of Fit Test was used to compare the observed contract distribution to a hypothesized distribution equivalent to the tariff distribution. (Calculated value of D = .563, critical value of D (O<= .05 2 tailed test) 8 .106 Summary: Extent of Use, Contracts VS. Tariffs The foregoing data analyses allowed the following summary statement to be made concerning the extent to which this carrier group's pricing behavior is characterized by the use of contracts vs. tariffs. 1. As measured by the percentage of each firm's revenue accounted for; and regardless of whether special tariffs or special items aimed at one or a few shippers are considered to function as contracts, regular route comnon carriers of general comnodities are now making greater use of tariffs than of contracts. Analysis of Data and Result Research Question 18 Research Question 18 was phrased: "Does carrier management see this (1A) as constituting a change since deregulation?" ‘Hlis question was treated for each individual rate category. 165 Contracts Few respondents felt that their use of contracts was less than it had been prior to deregulation, but the response was split as to whether the amount of contract use was more than before deregulation or the same as before deregulation. These results are displayed in Figure 6-4. Figure 6-4 Contracts as Change This is more than This is about the same This is less than before deregulation as before deregulation before deregulation 38 41 2 (46.9%) (50.6%) (2.5%) Value of x2 = 34.89 significant at .05 2 Of Value of x2 comparing 79 with 2 = 71.3, also significant Value of X2 comparing 38 with 41 = .05, NS at .05 2 Of This response pattern is consistent with the observation that this carrier group had been allowed to begin contracting activities after April 6, 1978 (I.C.C. Exparte 55 Sub 27), and should also be viewed in the context that 101 carriers Or 61.6% of those responding to Question 35A reported contract revenue of zero. The extent to which carrier contracting activity represents change since deregulation was summarized as follows: 1. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities report their contract activity to be greater than or equal to that prior to deregulation. 2. Carrier group behavior with respect to whether contract activity is more than before deregulation or about the same as before deregu- 166 lation does not differ significantly from the null hypothesis of equal proportions. Special Tariffs Or Special Items Which Are Aimed At One Or A Few Shippers While regular route common carriers of general commodities have not moved strongly in the direction of contracts per se, they have made a substantial change in the direction of greater use of individualized tariffs. This behavior serves some of the functions of contracting, in that these tariffs may be individualized for a shipper. These data appear as Figure 6-5. Figure 6-5 Change: Special Tariffs or Special Items Aimed at One or a Few Shippers This is more than This is about the same This is less than before deregulation as before deregulation before deregulation 120 27 4 (79.5%) (17.9%) (2.6%) Value of x2 = 149.90 significant at .05 2 Of 'Value of X2 comparing 120 with 31 = 51.28, also Significant This result was summarized by the following statement: 1. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities report their use of Special tariffs or special items aimed at one or a few Shippers to be more than before deregulation. Independentlerublished Tariff Schedules Carriers may also Opt to publish their own schedules of tariffs aimed at a large number of Shippers. Carrier executives were asked whether the percentage of revenue which they derived from such sched- 167 ules, not to include any special items aimed at one or a few shippers, constituted a change since deregulation. As they had with the Special tariffSln‘items aimed at one or a few shippers, carrier executives report a substantial change in the direction of a greater use of this tariff device. Data supporting this perspective appear as Figure 6-6. Figure 6-6 Change: Independently Published Tariff Schedules Aimed At A Large Number of Shippers This is more than This is about the same This is less than before deregulation as before deregulation before deregulation 102 33 4 (73.4%) (23.7%) (2.9%) Value of x2 = 109.4 significant at .05 2 Of Value of X2 comparing 102 with 37 = 29.47 also significant This result was summarized as follows: 1. The majority of regular route common carriers of general commodities report their use of independently published tariff schedules aimed at a large number of shippers to be more than before deregulation. Bureau Tariffs Bureau tariffs may be adjusted on an individual basis through independent actions to accomplish the functional results of either the Special tariff or item, or the independently published tariff schedule. Question 350 was worded so as to capture the use of bureau tariffs which had not been adjusted in this way. In this context, the largest number of carrier executives report less use of the bureau tariffs, but the minorities reporting the same use or more use are so substantial that, when combined, they are not a statistically significantly analler group 168 than the group reporting less use. Figure 6-7 illustrates this situaw tion. Figure 6-7 Change: Bureau Tariffs (Not Including Independent Actions Which Result In Special Tariffs Aimed At One Or A Few Shippers Or Independently Published Tariff Schedules Aimed At A Large Number) This is more than This is about the same This is less than before deregulation as before deregulation before deregulation 25 4O 86 (16.6%) (26.5%) (57.0%) Value of x2 = 40.5 significant at .05 2 Of [This compares the three category distribution to the null distribution of equal proportions.] Value of X2 with continuity correction = 2.649 not significant at either .05 or .10 1 Of [This compares the consolidation of more and same with the category less.] The results were summarized as follows: 1. When asked whether the percentage of revenue accounted for by bureau tariffs was more, the same, or less than before deregulation, the largest single group of regular route comnon carriers of general comnodities reports their use of bureau tariffs to be less than before deregulation. 2. Carrier behavior with respect to whether they report their use of bureau tariffs to be 1) less than before deregulation or 2) either more or the same as before deregulation does not differ signifi- cantly from the null hypothesis of equal proportions. 169 Analysis of Data and Result, Research Question 2A Research Question 2A was phrased: To what extent is carrier pricing behavior characterized by extensive discounting?" The research question was approached in several ways. Discounting was interpreted both as the offering of specific discounts and as price cutting. Price cutting, in turn, was examined in terms of deviation from bureau tariffs, and in terms of the relationship of revenues to costs. The results of these analyses are presented in turn. Discounting Interpreted as Specific Discounts In order to examine whether or not carriers were engaging in any of several specific discounting behaviors identified in the literature and in the exploratory interviews, responses to Question 36, Items A through N were used to categorize each respondent as engaging or not engaging in each named discount. The X2 Test, with continuity correction, was then used to compare the observed distribution with the null distributicnl of 50:50. The results of these procedures are sumnarized in Figure 6-8. These results allowed the summary statements in the previous chapter to be made concerning specific discounts. These statements (statements 1 a-e, 2 a-d, and 3 a-e) are not reproduced here. Price Cutting: Deviation From Bureau Tariffs The next data analysis sought to identify groups using contracts, special tariffs, items or schedules as vehicles to cut price, and to determine whether their use of these rate categories differed from that of the group as a whole. These groups are displayed in Figure 6-9. For each group so identified, the proportion of respondents in each rate category (contracts, etc.) was tabulated, and a figure was constructed to allow the comparison of their use of the rate category to that of the group as a whole. The Kolmogorov-Smirnov 2 Sample Test was used. 170 mz mz mz mz mz m we 4 mo. h< m2\m az< .aacxooa co\u=c mo>oe mao.~ om om no:_neoo .uemeo>oe maoac_¢:ou .e:_5cmu ecu «mo. mm Hm soc» new cu acoqmcacu cosoumzu anxo_a oo~.om veg Hm co\u:e xco>_—ou mo ace mo oe_h Rope. «em.afiu emu mH c_ oeseom_ev aeo>._ee Co San uo_coq we.» a :_:u_3 mzco>oc use. do me 25.—on so eocsmaoe moeoea_ea .aeee uopeoq oe_a o :_:u_z mmcccou oNo.m mm NR an umcamcoe mucmea_:m _ouoh newcoq oe_a a :_nu_: omoccou ha mwm. mm mm umcsmuoe mucoea_sm 4»; o_q_upsz Aacsoompu umacmocmmuv oepu oco an umaa_zm on on mucoeapsm NNH.m~ oe NHH Sea ea * ase_e_e a me_coeeoe mx mo m=4<> wz~w oHH mm on mod No we wz~w c mwa ow a and OH N me m H HoH me e NoH mm c mo~ mo NH mo Hm mm: mmmu uwz__mc mo Ace mo oe_h mun. w_ uczoom_c .aEm>w_ou mo ace uo_coq maps a :_:u_: macm>mc ce__ou an cocamcoe macoea_gm _cuoh nopcoa os_u u :_:uwz manage» an emcameoe mucosqvgm Page» uo_con we.» a =_:u_3 omcccou an umcamooe macoEQ_:m 4»; o_n_u_:z papa ago an uoaa_zm on cu mu:85q_zm be; mo * s=e_:_e a mcwcmucoh hzaoom~o mucaoom_a coed: o_e_ooqm o» pooqmoa :u_3 «mango m:_ucono¢ mcm_cccu ed-e ocsm_a 183 U) m we N mo. H< mz\m ON.mo~ om.mma om.~m~ mv.mm mN.o~ Ho.¢¢a mm.¢m Nx mo w=4<> a Add do A fie #ma o we mNH a cod mm m mm no N Ne mNH OH Hod mm mm: mmmu mmzoe uo:_nEoo .ucoeo>oe waochacou hzzoumuo wucaouw_o nose: o_m_ooam o» woodwom zap: omeogu m:_acoqom wcopcecu Aeose_oeeuv as-e acsm_u .3 184 m mm.N aoa m mm.mm mNa m ~N.NNH vma m m~.oN~ mmd m mo.m flea m ww.o~ mod m mm.o moa m mm.o me an H mo. H< mz\m zomhumamou maz<=u oz >h~=zchzou xpez wzcheoawa Nx do mao<> waw~¢¢oe no:_neou .ucoem>oe wzoacpucou .e:_EEmu on“ soc; use ou “Loeweccu Lesouwau aaxo_n co\uca xco>__oc mo Now Co oe_h ouc— e_ acaoow_n .xcm>__mu we was uo_coq oe_u a :_:uw: osco>mc cc__oo An umczwcme wucoeapzw pouch uo_coa we,“ a c.5uw; omcccou an umcaweoe wacoea_:w .auoh copcoa we.“ a :.:a_: omcccou Xe noczwooe wucoea_gw up; o_a_u_:z oe_u one up uoan_;w on o» wueoeq_:w A»; we N Essfie_e a m:_cmu:oh hzaoumaa wucsoow_o nose: o_e_omqm op Homewom =u_2 omeego m:_ucono¢ wco_cccu o~-e acsw_a 185 mz m we a mo. h< mz\m Nm.mH HAN No Nw.c¢ He NmH No.0m we NNH mo.w cod co mH.m mm as do.¢e Ne omH zoupumamou mwzh_:thzou rhuz oz-mommm wthmommm Nx mo m=4<> mmmfimm_cu :o.:=-=o: m:_m= mmpcm>__mu gmpucmag m mo.- om Nefl . «gas 58 acms_cu uaoc m=_n= Aupcoguzm m=_u_cq m co.o moH we m>o= cu m_aoma mm_am cao m:_zo__< mmu_>cmm \mmamc c_o;u can mcou_amqeou cao m mm.fim KN “as to aaua.3o=x ua__aoau m=_ao_a>ma mcopaao _o=o_umcmao\m:¢umxcms m om.o cod o“ an xoo_ o» m_ocoe cmuaqsou m:_m: »a_cozu:o m:_u_cq pa:_m m>oz m oo.m moH mo ca mpaoma m:_umxcue cao m:_3o__< xco: mm_om com mucaocmxuma mz em. mm Hm .a5_cm_mo_ ;u_; m_aoaa m=_c_: cmaq_=m was» cu mu_>com use umou cu cman_zm mg» »n umop>oca mz mo.~ a“ ma nucoaoc acmea.gm ua__auou m=.m= co H mo. p< m2\m az< Nx do was<> ¢z_¢ozz~ ho: * * m:o_um>occ_ umEmz u_w_umam :_ mcpmcmcm mcm_ccou mmno ac=m_c 199 mz mz mz w: H 30. h< mz\m az< e¢.m Ne.m~ mm.m o¢.~ w~.wm Km.m~ we. Nx do “344) OHH -~ mm mm mm mm mm wz~w_u xu_uoesoo _a_umam m=_m= zo-<>ozz~ m:o_um>o::H omewz u_»_umam cw m:_mom:m mcm_ccmu Aua==_a:ouv m~-o manned 200 mz oo.o mm mm u;m_mcc ca~_cm=_au=ou m=_qa_=m m 49.5 mod we m=o_555==ou u=m_mcc c_a m=_m= .aag mz ma.H cm on «CE. coc Accepv guaaxmm_a m=_m= m mm.oN mm meg m=,u_ca A.¥.<.av mo=_x ..a u:m_acc momco uwzqocmomm mz m~.~ KN mm 5555 =_ xuaa au_>cam mewuaao .395 m mm.mma Ha 00H u_;amcmomm 3o: cu mu.>cmm m=_uu< mucmxmmz co m mo.¢m KN ems new u;m_= “5 nup>cam m=_cmcco m ea.NmH a HRH sco>__5o u:m_=ca>o m=_cacco mcmsoumzu op :o_uu>o::_ mu_>cmm\mu_ca m om.mc 5m med m=_om5mm=m =_ .uams 5;“ mcpxap. Ammcmaxm m_= “av cmaa_=m m Nc.ma mms mm a 5“ m_m»_a=a .au_um_ao_ mcpuca> co 4 mo. c< m2\m Qz< Nx do u=s<> uz_uozz~ be: e * m:o_um>o::H nosez u.m_umam =_ m:_mmmcm mco_cccu Aum==_u=ouv a~-o mc=a_a 201 (I) '1, W V) (I) WWWWWWW (A we N m:. h< m2\m om.~m om.¢oH 5o.m~ No.mm oN.mNH ¢~.m~H ma.~m mo.m- m¢.¢m mo.HHH mm.~mH «N.M¢H ~.mm Nx H mm mm o co oHH m mm mm m moH Hm m mMH em m va we N vm on m mNH me m on moH 0 «HH mm H «NH ac H mNH we H moH wk mm: mme mozHu xuwuoeeou _o_umam mcpma mcmxcoz Hm:_scmu :o_::-:oz mco>ch =o_::-=oz ampuuwQa mcm>ch teem «open mHQoma mmHom mcou_umqeou co «mum—zocx mHmuoe cmuaasou mo_ca QHQomq mcwumxcoz mucaocmxuma muHum_ao_ m:_c_z mucoamc acmsa_gm umHHmuwa Hm~-o ac=m_c 5552 ..ac. zo-<>ozz_ meowua>occH umEmz u_w_umqm o» aumqmmm na_3 omcagu m:_acoamm mcm_ccmu II. 202 WWWWWWWW WWWW m mo m mo. H< mz\m o~.omH om.m¢~ mm.emH om.mm Ho.~m mo.H¢H om.m~H m~.Hm mm.om eo.-~ me.¢mH oH.m¢H Hm.wm Nx m um: mmuH othxommm mam~¢¢cmm m:_uu:u omH momcm UHgamcmomm 3m: cu mup>cwm Ne mucmxmm3\agm_= an mu_>cmm No xco>HHmu uga_=cm>o m:_cmwmo :o_uo>o::_ em m=_ummmm:m nomH as“ m:_xah HH mwmxpucm mu_um_mo_ mcpucm> we H.axm cm_ccouv mHmHHaco mu.am.mog He m:_u_cq n.35com mo mcouacmao cmczo zu_z mmmmmp QHch mm: “mo: Hm~-o ac=m_a 525: ..zcv othaommx onh<>ozzH mauHa¢o::H umEcz u_w_umqm oh aumqmmm su_3 mmcmsu m:_ucoama mcm_ccmu Hua==_u=ouv om-c 5139.1 203 mz mz \WWWWWW mo H mo. h< mz m mo.H om Hm.oH oo No. mo om.m moH oo.~m omH ~o.o~ emH Hm.H co o~.o~ mmH oo.o oo o~.¢H eHH mo.om va om.mm oNH o¢.m moH onhomzzoo mozhHothzoo :th othzoomm othmomum Nx co m=s<> mamH¢¢_u »u_nossou _u_umam m:_m: mcmxcoz .m:_scmu cowcaicoz mcm>pco :o_:ai=oz =m_uqu= mcm>_cu coca mUHcg «Haoma mmpam mLoHHHanou mo mmumpzocx mpouos cwuaaeoo mupca mpaoma mcpamxcaz mucaocmxuon mu_um_mo_ m:_c_: mucoamc acmeaHzm ump_uuma m~-c ma:m.u 555: ..ac zo_h<>ozz_ m=o_am>o::H uoEoz u_m_umam oh Howamom =u_3 mmcozo m:_ucoam¢ mcm_ccau Hm-o 513511 p~=ZHHzoo Ibo: Nx do w=4<> qu omH oNH mm moH me oNH ooH No NoH va HmH moH uozcmm m:_uu=o va moose uwcqwcmomm 3m: cu mu_>cwm Hm mucmxmm3\uzm.: an mu_>cmm No acm>meu ugmwccm>o m:_cmmwo =o_ua>o::_ mm m=_ummmm:m cumH msu m:_xap mH «Ham—ocm mu_am_mo_ m:_u:m> cc H.axm cmpccouv mpma—mcm mupampmoo cc m:_upcq oH=ELom mm mcoaocmao gonzo gu_; momma. q_ch mwz<=u m~-o mc=a_c 555: ..aa othmommm onh<>ozzH mauHamo=:H umsmz u_m_umam ch uuoammm zu_3 wmcogu mc_ucoamm mcm_ccmu Aua==_5=ouo Hm-o ac=m_c (Ill—D 205 report, the results of the investigation of each candidate type are presented. Predators The initial research expectations concerning predators conformed to a conventional economic definition of the term. Predators were seen as firms which had the resources to operate at break-even or a small loss during the initial period of deregulation and did so because of their confidence in their own ability to survive the "shake out“ period and become profitable after that. Question 8 was used to identify this candidate type. Question 8 divided the respondent group into two groups of nearly equal‘size as depicted in Figure 6-32. The results of the «cross tabulations which uncovered statistically significant differences between predators and non-predators are summarized below. Figure 6-32 Identification of Predators and Non-Predators 8. Since deregulation, we have operated at a break-even or a small loss because we are confident we will survive the shakeout and make our profit after that. True False 89 95 (48.4%) (51.6%) Value of x2 .14 us at .05 1 Of. The cross tabulations are the statistically significant (o<= .05) results of cross tabulating Question 8 by all other questions in the survey. Thus the candidate type or pricing behavior pattern is defined by Question 8 and members of the group are characterized by the ways in which they differ from non members. Since questions defining other ...—Ida‘s ' - A 206 candidate types or behavioral patterns were included in the cross tabulation, an understanding of whether or not carriers engage in one pattern to the exclusion of others may be derived. Similarities between members and non-members may be assumed for those questionnaire items not discussed. Sumary: The Candidate Pricing Type "Predator“ Examination of the characteristics of the candidate type “predator" resulted in the picture of an unwilling or ill-equipped predator at best. “Predators" did not believe that their costs were lower than those of competitors; in fact, the situation was the opposite. "Predators" were more likely than non-predators to report that powerful shippers had sometimes forced them to carry some shipments at a loss, and predators were less likely to report that they "walk away" from a shipper "most of the time" when he demanded rates which were close to their cost. They were, therefore, less likely to report themselves as being the candidate type “resister.” The impact of this combinaticnl of cost situation and pricing philosophy was predictable. Predators were more likely than non-predators to report the higher percentages of their traffic as being carried at rates “extremely close to costs“or “actually losing money.“ Predators were more likely to report that the percentage of traffic that they were actually losing money on was greater than before deregulation, more likely to report that their prices were lower than they were last year, and more likely to report their prices to be closer to their costs since deregulation. Predators were more likely to report that their firm was more profitable before deregulation, more likely to report 1983 year to date operating ratios of over 100%, and more likely to report having started to cut back service to some geOgraphic areas. 207 A type of pricing behavior does appear as a result of these relationships but predator is too aggressive a term for it. These firms are unwilling predators, unable to successfully resist the power of big shippers and crippled by a cost disadvantage. They are more nearly "victims" than ”predators.“ Those who survive will have been unwilling predators at best. To some extent supportive of the Stigler perspec- tive, the group in this economic situation was more likely to have been against the deregulation and more likely to have supported efforts to stop it prior to its institution. Price Leaders Price leaders were initially expected to be a group of carriers which attempted to price above market in the hope that other suppliers would follow. Thus a conventional definition of price leadership was used. The candidate pricing type price leader was examined in the same fashion as the predator type. In this case, identification of the candidate type was made using Question 10. This question divided the respondents into two sizable groups, although the price leader group was distinctly the smaller. This division is depicted in Figure 6-33. Figure 6-33 Identification 0f Price Leaders 10. Since deregulation we have tried to lead the price up True False 65 117 (35.7%) (64.3%) Value of x2 = 14.29 208 Question 10 was cross-tabulated by all other questions in the survey. Statistically significant differences between price leaders and non-price leaders are summarized below. The logic employed is parallel to that described for the candidate type ”pedator.“ Summary: The Candidate Pricing Type, “Price Leader“ Question 10 failed to differentiate reporting carriers" '- ' MOTEL... -Q......O..... .. .. -- tl MMQMNQM ............................. O 50‘ O , “MO - ~----~~---' - . ---'~-w—-—vm ...... "m - «IMmomm .--*. ._.- u"? mm.__0.._.0 ._O - “Lgmmbectpipfim’ .......................... O O**0~__”O~”_'O . O - ... ..WQWIFAMM..—m— -~'—--'~- - 1'“ MQEHEQQ.-O..._.O-.-O_ , - 1).- mwimmmhm .................................. . --..O .___O*, O. O O - vl mmm.-4:f: .H. "'T'T'W': 2..-.O_....- d1.-.0._...0- O O - zl WWW ......................................... O O O O O O I- PLEASE RESPOND TO THE FOLLOWING WESTIONS EY WRITING A SHORT ANSWER IN THE SPACE PROVIDED. : 33. “mum'mlmmmhmmmmmmbmmmm? - - - - - 39. WmdmummmmmhummmMmuu-mmi - - - - - 40. WWthdeMmmMMIeWIPh-ewwl - - - 41. Ammmhmumgmiltmwm - - 42. mmhmimmmmmw - 43. mwmummmmmmmwimm - 44. Minoanimwmmmmmmummi-mmuas. + - 45. WhammwckmmmuedIIO-yeu. °_' % - - THAT COMPLETES THE QUESTIONNAIRE. PLEASE RETURN IT IN THE PREPAID ENVELOPE PROVIDED. I WILL SEND A RESULTS SUMMARY IF - YOU REOUESTIPER THECOVERLET'TERI. - 044564 MSU to an AM mien-4 W W THANK YOU FOR YOUR TIME ! Mime-n Seen um" Pmemr - 245 APPENDIX B LETTER OF INTRODUCTION -_4- 246 #1 IC HIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY ERADUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION EAST LANSING ' MICHIGAN DEPARTMENT OF MARKETING AND FRANSPORTATION ADMINISTRATION ' 488244121 The pricing of motor carrier services in the deregulated environment is the topic of my doctoral research at Michigan State University. I'm sure you share my interest in the topic. Please help me out by completing the enclosed questionnaire and returning it to me in the prepaid envelope provided. If you request, I will send you a summary of the results when they are tabulated. If you want results mailed to you but you wish to remain anonymous. please put a convenient (friend or relative's) address on a separate sheet of paper and enclose that with the questionnaire. If you don't mind my knowing who you are. just enclose this cover letter with the questionnaire. The questionnaire has been developed using field interviews. so I'm sure you will find it interesting. It should take you only 10 to 15 minutes. Thanks very much for your time. Sincerely, /' / ’ f at my A/w “°'\ Woody Hoover 10839 Keystone Drive Ada. Michigan 49301 Encl. MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 247 a APPENDIX C FOLLOW-UP LETTER 1‘0} 248 1C HIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY \DUATE SCHOOL OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION EAST LANSING - MICHIGAN - 48826-1121 ’AR‘TMENT OF MARKETING AND \NSPORTATION ADMINISTRATION short time ago, I mailed a questionnaire to you which concerned motor carrier ~icing. Since that time, many of the questionnaires have been returned. If gu have already completed the form, I thank you for your help and considera- non. )wever, if you have not yet responded, would it be possible to find a few inutes to do so? Your response will help to insure that our understanding of Jur industry is accurate. You will remain anonymous and may receive a results ummary by simply enclosing an address with the questionnaire. f you have any questions or comments or if you have misplaced your question- aire and would like another mailed to you, please feel free to write or call me t home. My home address and telephone number are given below. greatly appreciate your cooperation. $incerely, “a? Mo“ loody Hoover 10839 Keystone Drive Ada, Michigan 49301 Telephone: (616)691-82l5 .ilSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 249 APPENDIX D DETAILED BREAKDOWN OF RESPONSES TO ITEM 35-E "OTHER“ RATE CATEGORIES 250 APPENDIX D EVALUATION OF RESPONSES FALLING INTO RATE CATEGORY E Record # % 0f Revenue Reported Statement 1 0 None 2 0 None 3 0 None 4 0 None 5 0 None 6 0 None 7 0 None 0 None 9 10 Owner Operators/Agent Nation-wide Carrier 10 0 None 11 0 None 12 0 None 13 0 None 14 0 None 15 5 Consolidation + Distribution Tariffs 16 40 “LTL“ 17 10 Cartage Leasing 18 0 None 19 0 None 20 0 None 21 0 None 22 0 None 23 0 None 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 39 4o 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 OOOOOOOOOOt—‘OOO ...—a O OOOOOOOOOOO 251 APPENDIX D (Continued) None None None None None None None None None None None None None None Local Hauls None None None None None None None None None None None 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 6O 61 62 -63 64 65 66 67 68 69 7O 71 72 73 74 75 00000 (JUN 00 OCOWOOOOOOOOOO ._a O 10 252 APPENDIX D (Continued) None None None None None None Combination 0f d) And Private Discount Tariff None None None None None None None None None None None None None None None None Exempt Commodities None None 253 APPENDIX 0 (Continued) 76 0 None 77 0 None 78 0 None 79 0 None 80 0 None 81 0 None 82 0 None 83 0 None 84 0 None 85 0 None 86 0 None 87 10 Leasing, Intrastate and No Tariffs 88 0 None 89 0 None 90 0 None 91 0 None 92 45 "i %" 93 0 None 94 0 None 95 0 None 96 0 None 97 2 Local Cartage 98 0 None 99 0 None 100 0 None 101 0 None 102 0 None 254 APPENDIX 0 (Continued) E! 103 0 None 104 0 None 105 0 None 106 0 None 107 10 Independent Actions 108 0 None 109 0 None 110 0 None 111 1 Section 22 Tenders 112 0 None 113 0 None 114 0 None 115 0 'None 116 0 None 117 0 None 118 0 None 119 0 None 120 0 ' None 121 0 None 122 0 None 123 0 None 124 0 None 125 0 None 126 20 Distribution 127 0 None 128 0 None 129 0 None J 255 APPENDIX D (Continued) 130 0 None 131 0 None 132 9 Exempt/Government Tenders 133 0 None 134 0 None 135 0 None 136 0 None 137 0 None 138 0 None 139 0 None 140 0 None 141 0 None 142 0 None 143 10 Cartage 144 0 None 145 2 Sec. 409 Frt. Forwarder 146 0 None 147 0 None 148 0 None 149 0 None 150 0 None 151 0 None 152 5 Government + Exempt 153 0 None 154 0 None 155 0 None 156 0 None 256 APPENDIX D (Continued) 157 0 None 158 0 None 159 0 None 160 0 None 161 10 Carloading 162 0 None 163 1 Government Traffic 164 0 None 165 0 None 166 0 None 167 0 None 168 0 None 169 25 Guaranteed Traffic Based on Low Cost Bid 170 0 None 171 0 None 172 0 None 173 0 None 174 0 None 175 0 None 176 0 None 177 0 None 178 1 Gov't. Tenders 179 0 None 180 0 None 181 0 None 182 0 None 183 184 185 257 APPENDIX 0 (Continued) 50 Blanket Discount Tariffs 0 None 25 None 258 APPENDIX E LISTING 0F DETAILED CROSS TABULATION RESULTS AVAILABLE BY SPECIAL REQUEST 259 APPENDIX E Some cross tabulations performed during this research were not included in the appendices. They are available from the author upon special request. These cross tabulations include: 1. Pricing Type Predator 2. Pricing Type Price Leader Pricing Type Shipment Targeter 3 4. Pricing Type S.B.U. 5. Pricing Type Cream Skimmer 6. Pricing Type Price Aggressor 7. Discounts and Revenue in Contract and Tariff Categories 260 APPENDIX F STATISTICALLY SIGNIFICANT DIFFERENCES BETWEEN CANDIDATE PRICING TYPE RESISTER AND NON-RESISTERS [at = .05] if m 261 Aseauae_cm.m cm_e om.s .am.mev mm Aao.aev mm Axm.mev mm m Axo.mav me Au~.o~v as Axe.mmv on m mcmum_mmguco: cog“ apex._ egos one mgmum_mmmg u umamuwpomcoo mazoem Loumpmmguco: sup: Nx wouumggouv no.“ u Nx Aus.emv mm Ano.mmv em Aum.emv ON h Acozv »_meaa Aeozv ~\H saoa< Acoum_mmmv umoz a~3< x_mz .aesa Lou‘s u_$ocq Lao ages can zuaomxezma mgu m>_>cam .._: m: use... £8328 we... a; 3:33 3.2 :25 a .5 :26 x33 so 33qu 26: m3 53339.2. 35m .8 m.mgoueumca on as mgmum_mmg-co: cogs »_mxp_ mmop use mcmum_mmau Axo.mmv ma .am.amv as Axe.sev em h £32 “:93 05 a: 9.3.. It. .35 acmcCeoo 93 35 3:32. 39. $2 :25. a .3 53 game: as 3323 3 9:3: ma 3 333.55 “.33.. .35 .8523 3 333.. 5:. 33335.5: so: Lat; mgmuflmmm Aucmu_m.:m_m capo om.m u umueup—omcoo museum gmumpmme-co: :a_: Nx umuumggoov me.m n Nx Aeozv a_mgem Aeozv ~\~ “soa< Agmum_mmzv “no: s~z< x_az .=o_a_umaeoo Lao mo umoe cog» Lesa. mew mumou Lao .mo m.=o_u_umqsoU L_o:a mo omega ens» em:o_ use mumou L_m=a Hes» “Logo; on .mamou cu sumammc ea.) mcmum_mme-=oc seem Lemm_u memam_mmm H.x_gums on“ mo muooame o~_goaumce:u ;o_cz macmemaoam mc_xw__a2e mew mommgucmeoq :p mucoemuoumu mmmhmHmmaszoz oz< mmmpmHmma zmmxpmm mmuzmmumamolhz44mz cu we: Ee_m m=_xozgu e .mgmaa_=m _=mgo3oa ga_; mmm:_m=n ow on egowwe cu m_ne on o» copuo_:mmgmu oucpm .mao m.u_wocq mgu a: mon ca mgmqa_=m gmsuo Co ooze—ea a m>ms on we: ELPC m:_xoseu a .=o_ue_=mmgmu moc_m mcmqa_;m Pamemzoa gap: mmm:_m:n on cu seamen .3 2%. on 3 HS: magma 3 38:. .32 was .33 323 E 3:93 emuflmmeuco: so: Let; $3333 .mgoee_xm eamcu as ou mm>pmmsoga «Loam; xmsa emnumgz on uomawme =a_3 mgmum_mmgaco: scum Loempu memumfimma Aueeo.mp=m_m om_e No. mu omuou__om=ou manoem cmumwmme co: zap: mx umuomeeoov om. mu Nx is .NSV lad. Nev m em Aeozv a.staz Aus.mfiv Ana.smv m mm Aeozv ~\H “soa< Aum.mmv Au~.Nev as on Atmsm_ma¢v “we: a L saz< x_e3 .mmo_ e um magm5q_sm esom xgeeo cu m: emote» mme_umsom w>eg memaa_:m .zmemzoa .:o_um—=mmemc mocpm .Nac m.mmo_ a an mu=m5a_gm «sow xegeo cu Sega emote» mmepumeom m>o= mgmaq_sm .53on 532332. 3:; “.2: ocean 3 38:— 32 0.5 33335 .33 a as 35535.. 3.3 Chico 3 .53 333 $6: 2335 .3338 .852: 3 333.. 5:. Lot; 3:93 LouflmmTS: new $3.33. avmacpucouv m x~ozumm< .m .i‘.(.-l4¢.(f\\ L )hp:¢L::< 264 Aacou_$_=m_m ompm ac.o u umumc__om=ou maaogm Lmum_mmg-=o= ;u_z Nx nmaumggouv ¢H.m u mx Aam.o V Aa~.omv o mm Acozv apogom Auo.o v Aua.mmv ¢ em Acozv ~\q “aoa< An~.¢wv Aam.mmv ma He Agmampmmav umoz :o_uo_=mmgmo gmum< copes—amwgmo mgommm au3< x_m3 umpaoupmogn mgos Egpm gag» mo: ems: .mmo m.:o_um_=mmgmc gouge mpnuu.moga ages ogmz amgu “as“ ugoamg cu a_mx_. uses was copum_:mmgmu 388 «33:95 95:. 98: 3:... a2... foam... 3 38:— 33 9:. £3335 £23333“. m5 :5: LS 8.33 33:33 93:. «.33 35 35mg: 3 33mm; 5.: 3:83 33397.8: 29:. at; 8.3.9.33. Aucou_$_=m_m om_m m.m u umamu._om:ou maaogm Lmum_mmgsco= cap; mxv mm.m~ u «x Aam.m V AxN.~HV Aao.omv m N m¢ Acazv »_og~¢ Aa~.H V Axe.m V Aam.emv A ~ om Acozv «\H H=OQ< Axm.~fiv Aao.mHV Aum.mov N AH mm Agmam_mm¢v “we: co_am_:mmgwc :o_um_=mmgma =o_um_=mmgmo xu2< x_u3 mgo;mm cmzh mmmJ mgommm m< mEom mg» mgommm gunk mgoz "m_ :o m:_mo— x_—o=uuw mum m3 umsa uwmmagu Lao mo a mpgh .mmc m.mmm_ go wEom mzu m. a_ waxy ugoamg ou »_mx__ ages use cowuo_=mmgmu mgommn saga mgos m_ :o m=_mo_ »__m=uuc mgu xmzu ans» u_mmmgu mo mmoucwugma ms» ungu ugoqmg ou apmx__ mmmp mum Amgu was» :_ mnaogm gmum_mmg-:o: scum gawk—u mgmam_mmmg .:o_uo—=mmgmu mgommn coca mmm_ Lo ago: m. :o m:_mo_ a__u:uuo mus 35 ”.23 fitab we $358.3 2.... $52.: 3 33mm: 5; mgmuflmmguco: :8: 3:2. mgmamwmwm Acm==_a=ou~ L xHazu¢¢< .m 265 apex__ egos ego mgeum_mmmV Aueeu_m_:m_m em_e m.a u eeuee__emeeu meeegm geum_mmgucee new: NxV mH.HH u mx Axe.eNV ARN.MNV Aam.m V NH me n AcezV »_mge¢ Aam.meV Aam.-V .nm.eHV a me N Acon ~\V esca< A*K.m V AaK.HNV Ame.-V m em Ne AgmumwmmmV “we: geee gm>e geee-em gem smug: >d3< V_m3 ~e_ueg m:_uegeee euee ea gem» mama gee» mp ewe: apeueewxegee< .meo H.Reee Lm>c mo e32 mezegeee cm 9.22. “seem: 3 38:— 32 ecu 3m :23 new. we e38. mezegeee ea 9.26; teem... ea .me_aeg me_uegeee ea Homemeg :u_z meeegm Leum_meg-eee see» gmmm_e mgeum_mem Aueee_m_em_m em_e mm.m~ n emuee__emeee meeegm gmum_mmgueee :u_; NxV em.mH u mx Axe.e V Axe.e V Age.“ V Age.e~V .xm.¢eV H e e ed Km Acon »_mgma Axe.m V Axe. V Axe.eeV Au~.-V AuH.VeV m e e NH mm Acon N\V a:on< Axm.eeV Axe.eVV Axe.eVV Axe.“ V Aam.emV e e e e mm AgoememmV “we: a+ee eee-ee noe-ee ae¢-HN ae~-e amz< ¥_~3 mgeee_gm we 39.5: mm:— e an ems: 333:3. :23 ease—See :uemeeeeeef se,; 32.96.. a Ve 5 .e.mmc H.ee=e>eg g_m:u we egos ge nae Lee eeeeuee mwm_geu omega ease ugeeeg ea x_ex__ 3e... ece 2.52: :23 we .33 ..e ace Lea. .2588 €335. we geese: 3...: e an ewe: mgr—:3 eeszeee azeeeeeeeefi we 3.32.3 e23 teem: 3 :9:— mmm: 95 9.33.33 6:23 acme—.83.... ye 3385.». V3 gem 25.588 2.55.. we 3358.3 93 3 3.83.. :3: 3393 3332.5: se,: Len—fie 98:33. nwmacmuceuv m xuozmqm< .oH .m 266 APPENDIX G CHANGE IN CONTRACT AND TARIFF BEHAVIOR CROSS-TABULATED BY ALL OTHER RESPONSES STATISTICALLY SIGNIFICANT RESULTS [ac = .05] 267 STATISTICALLY SIGNIFICANT RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN CHANGE IN TARIFF 0R CONTRACT BEHAVIOR AND OTHER BEHAVIORS AND CHARACTERISTICS. [Statements in parentheses are amplifying statements which characterize the matrix.] Supporting data for each statement comprise the second section of this appendix. A. Group 1 Change in the Use of Contracts Statistically significant differences between the groups using more, the same or fewer ("less“) contracts than prior to deregulation are summarized below. 1. The groups differ with respect to whether they are strategic business units. [Those using "more“ contracts are more likely to be strategic business units.] The groups differ with respect to the use of statements sent to shippers. [Those using "more" contracts are more likely to send shipper statements showing how much he has saved off of the published rate.) The groups differ with respect to carriage of shipments at a loss prior to deregulation. [Those using ”more“ contracts are more likely to agree that the tariff structure had caused them to carry some shipments at a loss prior to deregulation.] The groups differ with respect to change in the percentage of traffic which is not profitable. [Those using ”more“ contracts are less likely to report that the 1 of traffic that they are actually losing money on is more than before deregulation, more likely to report it is the same and less likely to report that it is less than before deregulation.] The groups differ with respect to change in the use of special tariffs or items. [Those using "more“ contracts are more likely to report that special tariffs or special items are more or less than before deregulation and less likely to report that they are the same.] The groups differ with respect to change in the use of schedules of independent tariffs. [Those reporting change in the use of contracts are more likely to report change in the use of schedules of independent tariffs.] The groups differ with respect to change in the use of bureau tariffs. [Those using “more" contracts are most likely to report using fewer (“less") bureau tariffs, and those making less use of contracts are most likely to report using more ’ bureau tariffs.] 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 268 APPENDIX 6 ONE (Continued) The groups differ with respect to the use of aggregate dis- counts. [Those using more contracts are less likely to have started offering aggregate discounts, more likely to be offering more of them, less likely to be offering less and more likely to have never offered it.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts differ with respect to offering the discount for Inultiple LTL shipments within a time period. [The group using more contracts also is more likely to have started the use of this discount or made more use of it.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to offering the discount for total shipments measured by tonnage within a time period. [The group using more contracts is more likely to have started using or have made more use of the discount, and less likely to have made less use of or stopped using the discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to offering the discount for total shipments as measured by dollar revenue. [The group using more contracts is more likely to have started or made more use of this discount, and less likely to have made the same use of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to offering the discount for day of delivery. [The group using more contracts is more likely to have started offering this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of contracts also differ with respect to offering the discount for time of day of delivery. [The group using more contracts is more likely to have started the use of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of contracts also differ with respect to offering the discount for customer transport to and from the terminal. [The group using more contracts is more likely to have started or engaged in either more or the same use of this discount.] The groups differ with respect to the discount for continuous moves, combined moves and/or backhaul. [The group using more contracts is more likely to have started or used more of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of contracts also differ with respect to offering the discount for transport to and from certain areas or along certain routes. [The group using more contracts is more likely to have started or engaged in more use of the discount.] 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 269 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of contracts also differ with respect to the specific innovation of allowing marketing people to have final pricing authority. [The group using more contracts since deregulation is more likely to have started or made more use of the innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of contracts also differ with respect to the specific innovation of using road drivers to make “peddle" deliveries. [The group using more contracts since deregulation is more likely to have made more use of the innovation and less likely never to have made use of it.[ The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to the specific innovation of pricing after a complete market analysis. [The group using more contracts since deregulation is more likely to have started or made more use of the innovation and less likely to have never used the innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to the specific innovation of using trip leases with owner operators. [The group using more contracts since deregulation is more likely to have started, made more or the same use of the innovation and is less likely to have made less use or never have made use of the innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to the specific innovation of using F.A.K. pricing. [The group using more contracts since deregulation is more likely to report making more use of the innovation since deregulation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to the type of loss reported in the open-ended questionnaire. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to the size of the firm. [The group using more contracts since deregulation is less likely to be a small company and more likely to be a medium or large company.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts also differ with respect to revenue losses reported. [The group using more contracts was less likely to report losses of over 20%.] 270 APPENDIX 6 ONE (Continued) Groupfz Change in the Use of Special Tariffs or Items Statistically significant differences between those making more, the same or “less" use of special tariffs or items are sumnarized below (0k 1. .05). the groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to their willingness to carry shipments at a loss if those shipments were part of a profitable overall package for a shipperu. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to agree that they would carry such shipments. Thus, they are less likely to be shipment targeters.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to whether or not they report that they still lose on those on those shipments which they lost on prior to deregulation. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to agree that they still lose on those shipments.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to whether or not they report that it is now harder to make up a loss on one shipment by getting increased rates on another due to increased competition. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report this as being harder.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ as to whether they now support efforts to roll back or slow the advance of deregula- tion. [Those making more use of special tariffs or special items are less likely 'to report that they now support these efforts.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items differ as to whether contracts they enter into are always lower, usually lower or rarely lower than the bureau tariffs which would ordinarily apply to the traffic. They also differ as to whether they enter into contracting. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ as to whether these special tariffs and special items are lower than the bureau ‘tariff that would ordinarily apply to the traffic. [The group making more use of special tariffs and special items is more likely to report that these tariffs and items are always or usually lower than the bureau tariff, and less likely to report that they are never lower.] 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 271 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or special items also differ as to the x of traffic that they are actually losing money on. [The group making more use of special tariffs and special items is less likely to report that they are losing on none of their traffic and more likely to report that they are losing on 75-99% of it or all of it.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or special items also differ as to whether they report initiating price competition often, once in a while or rarely. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report initiating price competition “once in a while“ and less likely to report initiating it ''rarely."] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ in the percentage of their revenue accounted for by contracts. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ as to whether they report their use of schedules of independent tariffs to constitute a change since deregulation. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ in the percentage of their revenue accounted for by schedules of independent tariffs. [The group reporting more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report schedules of independent tariffs accounting for O- 20% of their revenue. J The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or item also differ as to whether they report their use of bureau tariffs to constitute a change since deregulation. [The group reporting more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report a change in the use of bureau tariffs.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ with reSpect to their offering of the aggregate discount. [Those reporting either more or less use of special tariffs or items are more likely to report having started the use of the aggregate discount and are less likely to report having never used it. the group re- porting more use of special tariffs or special items is also more lakely to report making more use of the aggregate dis- count. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 272 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ as to their use of the discount for total shipments measured by tonnage withiriia time period. [The group making more use of Special tariffs or items is more likely to report change in the use of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ as to their use of the discount for day of delivery. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report that they- have started or made either more or less use of this dis- count.] . The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs or items also differ as to their use of rebates or refunds after a shipper has purchased a certain amount. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items also is more likely to report change in the use of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to the use of "negotiable" discounts. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to have started the use of this type of discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to their-IJse of discounts calculated as a % off a bureau tariff. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to have started and less likely never to have used this dis- count.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to their use of the specific innovation of allowing marketing people to have pricing authority. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report having started and less likely to report making the same use of this innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to their use (If the specific innovation of developing detailed knowledge of competitors and their rates and services. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report having started or making more use of this innovation and less likely to report making the same use of it.] 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 273 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to their use of the specific innovation of allowing road drivers to make “peddle“ deliveries. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report having started or making the same use of this innovation and less likely to report having made less use or never having used the inno- vation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of special tariffs or items also differ with respect to their use of the specific innovation of non-union drivers. [The group making more use of special tariffs or items is more likely to report making more use of or never having used this innovation, and is less likely to have reported making the same use of this innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of Special tariffs and items also differ with respect to their use of the specific innovation of non-union terminal workers. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs and items also differ with respect to the use of the specific innovation of pricing after a complete market analysis. [The group reporting more use of special tariffs and items is less likely to report the same level of use of this innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs and items also differ with respect to the use of the specific innovation of in-depth logistical analysis of a shipper's distribution system at carrier expense. [The group reporting more use of special tariffs and items is more likely to report that they have started or made more use of this innovation and less likely to report that they have made the same or less use of this innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs and items also differ with respect to the use of the specific innovation of vending logistical analysis at shipper expense. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs and items also differ with respect to the use of the specific innovation of offering service at night and on weekends. [The groups reporting more use of special tariffs and items is not as likely to report making less use of this innovation.] 274 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) Group 3 Change in the Use of Independently Published Tariff Sthedules Statistically significant differences between those making more, the same or less use of independently published tariff schedules are summarized below (Gk = .05). 1. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to whether they are likely to report that they are SBU's. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to whether their parent company holds businesses other than trucking. [Those reporting no change are less likely to be held by firms holding other businesses.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to whether they would carry shipments at a loss if those shipments were a part of a profitable package for a shipper. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to whether they report that powerful shippers have negotiated their prices on traffic much closer to costs since deregulation. [The group making more use of independent schedules is more likely to report that powerful shippers have been able to do this.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to whether they report their special tariffs or items as being always, usually, rarely or never lower than bureau tariffs. [The group making more use of independent tariffs were more likely to report their special tariffs or items as always lower.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to whether they report these independent tariff schedules as being always, usually, rarely or never lower than bureau tariffs. [The group making more use of independent tariffs schedules was more likely to report these schedules as being always lower.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to the % of traffic that they report actually losing money on. [Those reporting no change in the use of independent tariff schedules are more likely to report losing on 1-24% or none of their traffic. Those making more use of independent tariff schedules are more likely to report losing on 50-74% or all of their traffic.) 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 275 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff structures differ as to whether they report change in their use of contracts. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ in their use of contracts. [The group making more use of independent tariffs is more likely to report that contracts account for 0-20% of revenue and more likely to report that they account for 41-80% of revenue.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to whether they report their use of special tariffs or items to be more, the same or less than prior to deregulation. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ in the percentage of revenue that they report as derived from special tariffs or items. [The group making more use of independent schedules is more likely to report that special tariffs or items account for (L20% of their revenue and less likely to report that they account for 81% or more of their revenue.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ as to whether they report their use of bureau tariffs or items to be more, the same or less than prior to deregulation. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ in the percentage of revenue that they derive from bureau tariffs. [The group making more use of independent schedules is less likely to report 0-20% of their revenue accounted for by bureau tariffs, and more likely to report 41-80% of their revenue accounted for by bureau tariffs.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in the extent to which they report "other“ rate categories to be more, about the same, or less than before deregulation. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in the extent to which they report making use of the aggregate discount. [The group making more use of independent tariff schedules is more likely to reprrt making more use of having stopped using the dis- count. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 276 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in the extent to which they report making use of the discount for total shipment by tonnage. [The group making more use of independent tariff schedules is more likely to report making either more or less use of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in the extent to which they report making use of the discount for transportation to and from certain areas and along certain routes. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in the extent to which they make use of individually-negotiated discounts. [The group making more use of independent tariff schedules is less likely to report never having made use of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in their use of discounts calculated as a % off of a bureau tariff. [The group inaking more use of independent tariff schedules is more likely to report having started or having made more use of this dis§ount and less .likely to report never having made use of it. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in their use of the specific innovation of using detailed shipment reports provided by the shipper to cost out service to that shipper. [The group Inaking more use of independent tariff schedules is more likely to report making “more“ use of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in their use of the specific innovation of using non-union drivers. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules also differ in their use of the specific innovation of zip code pricing. [The group making more use of independent tariff schedules is more likely to report having started this activity and less likely to report never having taken part in it.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ in their use of the specific innovation of formula pricing. [Groups indicating change, either more or less, in the use of independent tariff schedules are more likely to have started the use of this innovation.] 277 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) 24. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ in their use of the specific innovation of taking the lead in suggesting price- service innovation. [The group making more use of independent tariff schedules is more likely to report having started the use of this innovation.) 25. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of independent tariff schedules differ in their use of the specific innovation of F.A.K. pricing. [Those groups indi- cating change, either more or less, in the use of independent tariff schedules are more likely to have started the use of this innovation.] Group 4 Change in the Use of Bureau Tariffs Statistically significant differences between those making more, the same, or less use of bureau tariffs are summarized below (ox = .05). 1. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ with respect to whether their parent company is encouraging them to invest in truck transportation. [The group making less use of bureau tariffs is more likely to be owned by a parent firm which is encouraging investment in truck transportation.] 2. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ with respect to whether they would carry a shipment at a loss if it were a part of a profitable overall package. [The group making less use of bureau tariffs is more likely to report that they would carry such traffic, thus they are less likely to report themselves to be shipment targeters.] . 3. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ with respect to whether they agree that the tariff structure prior to deregulation caused them to carry some traffic at a loss. [The group making less use of bureau tariffs was more likely to agree with the statement.) 4. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ with respect to whether they agree that it is harder to make up a loss on one shipment by getting increased rates on another due to increased competition. [Those making more use of bureau tariffs were less likely to agree with that statement.) 5. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ as to whether they agree with the statement that the shipments they are losing money on and the shipments they are making money on have changed since deregu- lation. [The group deriving “about the same" percentage of revenue from bureau tariffs was least likely to agree with the statement.) 10. 11. 278 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ as to whether they now support efforts to roll back or slow the advance of deregulation. [The groups deriving "more" or “about the same" percentage of revenue from bureau tariffs were more likely to report that they supported those efforts.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ as to whether they report the contracts they engage in to represent rates which are always, usually, rarely or never lower than bureau tariffs. [The group using bureau tariffs to a lesser degree than prior to deregu- lation was more likely to report contracts to be always lower while the group using bureau tariffs more than before deregu- lation was more likely to report contracts to be usually lower.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ as to whether they report their special tariffs or special items to be always, usually, rarely or never lower than bureau tariffs. [The group using bureau tariffs to a lesser degree than prior to deregulation was more likely to report contracts to be always lower than bureau tariffs, while the group using bureau tariffs more than before deregullation was more likely to report contracts to be usually lower. The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ as to whether they report their independent tariff schedules to be always, usually, rarely or never lower than bureau tariffs. [The group using bureau tariffs to a lesser degree than prior to deregulation was more likely to report their independent tariff schedules always to be lower, while the group making more use of bureau tariffs since deregulation are most likely to report their independent tariff schedules to be usually lower.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ as to the percent of their traffic which they report as having rates extremely close to costs. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs is more likely to report that 49% or less of their traffic falls into this category and is less likely to report that 50-99% falls into the category. This group is also more likely to report that all of their traffic falls into the category.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ as to whether they classified themselves as being strongly against, moderately against, no opinion/neutral, moderately for or strongly for deregulation prior to its passage. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 279 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) Groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ as to whether they are local, regional or national firms. Groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ in the degree of change in the use of contracts. [The group reporting bureau tariffs to be less than before deregulation are most likely to report contracts as being more. The group reporting bureau tariffs as being the same are most likely to report contracts as the same and the group reporting bureau tariffs to be more are the most likely to report contracts as being less.] Groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ in the degree of change in the use of special tariffs and items. Groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ in the percentage of revenue accounted for by special tariffs or items. Groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ in the degree of change in the use of independent tariff schedules. Groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ in the percentage of their revenues accounted for by bureau tariffs. Groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ in the degree of change in the use of "other" tariffs. Groups which differ in the degree of change in the use of bureau tariffs also differ in their behavior concerning the aggregate discount. [The group making less use of bureau tariffs is more likely to report more use or less use of this discount and less likely never to have used it.) Groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their behavior concerning the discount for total shipments measured by dollar revenue within a time period. [The group making less use of bureau tariffs is less likely never to have used this discount.] Groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their behavior concerning the discount for day of delivery. The group making use of bureau tariffs to "about the same" degree is most likely to report never having used this discount. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. 280 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs differ with respect to their use of the discount for time of day of delivery. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs was more likely to have made more or less use and least likely to report never having used the discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs differ with respect to their use of the discount for customer transport to and from the terminal. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs is more likely to report using more or less of the discount and least likely to report never using the discount.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the discount calculated as a percent of a bureau tariff. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the specific innovation of using detailed shipment reports provided by the shipper to cost out service to that shipper. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the specific innovation of allowing marketing people to price. [Those using bureau tariffs to about the same degree are more likely to report that they have never used this innovation.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in the use of the specific innova- tion of developing detailed knowledge of competitors and their rates and services. [The group that is making more use of bureau tariffs is more likely to report having started and less likely to be making the same use of this discount.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in the use of the specific innova- tion of allowing sales people to have pricing authority. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs is more likely to have started and less likely to have used more, the same or less of this innovation. The group making about the same use of bureau tariffs is most likely to report never having made use of this innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in the use of the specific innova- tion of using road drivers to make peddle deliveries. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the Specific innovation of the use of non-union terminal workers. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs is more likely to report having started or making more use of this innovation.) 31. 32. 33. 34. 35. 36. 37. 281 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the Specific innovation of pricing after a complete market analysis. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs is the most likely to report having started this behavior but the least likely to report using more of it. The group using bureau tariffs u: about the same degree is most likely to respond that they are making the same use of this innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the specific innovation of zip code pricing. [The group reporting about the same use of bureau tariffs is least likely to report having started and most likely to report never having used this innovation.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the specific innovation of providing in-depth logistical analysis of a shipper's distribution system at carrier expense. [Those using bureau tariffs to about the same extent are least likely to report having started or having made more use of the innovation and the most likely to report making the same or less use of this innovation.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the Specific innova- tion of taking the lead in suggesting price service innovation to customers. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the specific innovation of adding service to new geographic areas. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs was most likely to report having started this behavior while the group making leSS use of bureau tariffs was most likely to have made more use of the innovation. The group using about the same amount of bureau tariffs was most likely to report making the same use of this innovation.] The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the Specific innovation of F.A.K. pricing. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs is most likely to report having started this innovation while the group making less use of bureau tariffs is most likely to report making more or the same use of the innovation.) The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in their use of the Specific innovation of using T.O.F.C. for line haul. [The group making more use of bureau tariffs is most likely to report having Started or never having used this innovation.] 282 APPENDIX G ONE (Continued) 38. The groups which differ in the degree of change in their use of bureau tariffs also differ in the year the company was founded. 283 Ago.ooVV N ANN.N0 V NN Vam.am V mV m Axo.ooNV N ANN.NN V om Aam.oo V NN m Ago. V o ANN.NN V NV Aum.oo V NN h NzN=NN new xcosssm mama o x~ozm¢m< z— mhzmzuh~hmz Nae. V o ANN.NN V NN ANN.NN V mN cosh mmmN NNo.ooNV Nae. V Nae. V Nae. V N o o o NNN.¢ V NNN.N V ANN.¢ V NNo.mN V N N N eN ANN.N V NN¢.m V ANN.NN V NNN.NN V N N NN SN mmmN asam mcoz omuguum A.um—o mhmz Nae. V o NNo.NN V NN ANN.NN V SN Nm>mz Ago. V NNS.N V Ago. V nmaaoum Nao.ooNV Ago. V Ago. V N o o NNo. V NNN.N V NNS.N V o S N NNo. V NNS.N V ANN.oN V o N S mmmN mEom wee: Nno. V o NNN.SNV N NNN.NN V NN SNNLNNN uw<220h >m omm=mm VH4 meVthz NSSSSNNSSNV ozN N xNszNNS NN.ooN u Nx cash mmmN Seam SSN NSSNS cash mcoz NNNSNNzoN NUNNV oNS ~N.mm u Nx can» mmmN QENN agN NSSNS cogh ago: NNNmz umqaoum NNo. V o NNN.NN V SN NNN.NN V NN Nm>mz NNo.ooNV NNN.NN V usem NNo.ooNV waN Nae. V o ANN.N V N NNN.NN V o SSNLNNN >mu>~4mo mo >mz ¢m om¢=maz NNo.ooNV N NNS.N V N NNo. V o NmaN o o o ANN.oN V NNS.N V ANS.N V NN N N ANN.NN V ANN.NN V ANN.NN V NN NN N asoN ago: oaagoNN Vmz NNo.ooNV Ago. V Ago. V N o o NNo. V NNo.N V NNo. V o N o NNo. V NNN.N V ANN.N V o N N mmaN msam umugoum NNNNNNmo No NS: go N:NN NoaSSNNoouV ozN a xNozNNNS No.No u Nx cosh NNaN aENN ago NoooS can» «go: NNNSNNzoa NNoNV SNS oN.oN u NN cash mmaN aENN aoN Nooo< cash ago: NNNSNNzoa NNoNV NNS 290 ga>az Ago. V Ago. V ANN.N V oaoooum ANN. V o ANS.NN V NN ANN.NN V NN L0>wz NNo.ooNV N ANN.NN V N NNN.N V N NNaN Ago. V Ago. V Ago. V o o o ANN.NN V NNN.oN V ANN.oN V N S N .NNN.NN V NNN.NN V ANN.NN V o N - oN anm ago: naugoam moz awzamzoo .Hzm:m>o: mao=z_pzou NoaooNNoooV ozN.o NNNZNNNS NN.NS u Nx cosh NNaN asom acu uaon< cash ago: NNNSNNzoo NNNNV NNS NN.NN u Nx cosh NNaN asoN aoN NoooS cosh ago: NNNSNNzoo NNNNV NNS 291 NNo.oN V NNo.oN V ANN.NN V ga>az NNo.ooNV N \ NNN.NN V NN NNS.NN V NN ga>az ANN.SN V N ANN. V o asom ago: NNo.oN V N NNN.N V N NNN.N V N naugaum mVoomm mam>~ao oaz ANN. V NNS.N V NNN.N V oaoooum NN.NN V NNN.S V Ago. V NNaN NNo.oNNV N NNN.NN V N ANS.N V N ga>az Ago. V Ana. V Ago. V o o o NNN.NN V NNo.NN V NNS.N V N N N ANN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NN oN N asoN ago: oaNgoNN mach<¢mmo muzzo 1h“: mumVaz NNN.NS V NN .N NNN. V o .N NNo.oN V NN .N NNN.N V N .N NNN. V o NNN.SN V SN NNN.NN V N asom NNN. V o NNN.NN V NN NNS.NN V NN ago: NNS.N V omhmommx mea mo mm>H NNN.NNNV N NNN.SN V N ANN.SN V N oaNgoNN NZNNNNN N.:.<.NV NNzN: NNN NNNNNNN Ana::_u:ouV ozh o xNozmoa< anN as» uaon< cosh ago: mhuz<¢zou mo mNHm ll \DNQOS NNo.oN V NNN. V .N .a NoaNNNNooNV ozN N NNNZNNNN mn.ma u Nx cozh NNaN asoN aNN Nooo< coo» ago: mNuo NN-NN NNN.NN V SN NNN.NN V N oduo mmmum NoaooNNooNV NNN N xNozNNNN NN.NN u Nx cosh NNaN asoN aNN Noooa cos» ago: N + h mam NN.NN u Nx cosh NNaN agoN aNN aooo< cosh ago: mhuuzoz szmoN >NN<2Hu< uNmmaz NNagom NNNosm: Nxo3N< NNNNNNN NNNNNN oN NNNaz oaoooum NNaN asom ago: oaNgon N + N mom NNaz 33on 33 9:8 ago: oaNgon N + N Nam NNzooNNNN NNNNNNNNNV NNN :NzNzN: NzNNNNNNN NoNNV SNN NoaNNNNooNV ozN N xNoszNN 303 NNN.NNNV NNo.SN V NN NNN.NN V NN ga>az NNN.NN V NNN.NN V SN NNS.NN V NNN ga>az Nae. V o Nae. V o NNN. V N NNaN NNN. V o NNN. V o NNN.N V N NNaN NNN. V o NNN.S V N NNN. V o aENm NNN.NN V N NNN.S V N NNN. V o anm NNN. V NNN. V o o NNo.S V NNo.N V N N NNN.S V NNN.SS V N NN ago: oaNgon mozzuum mo mmNmm>NNmo mo >az NNN. V NNN. V NNN. V NNN.NN V o o o N NNN.N V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N N N N NNN. V NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V o o NN oN NNaN agom ago: oaNgNNm :(mmam mac a < m< ouNaz aENm ago: oaugoum NNNzNooNNN NNNNNNNNNNV =NNNSNNNNNN N.NN= NoaSNNNoooV NNN N NNNzNNNN NN.NS u Nx NNNN NNaN anm as» Naon< conN ago: N + N NNN NENNV NNN mm.m~ u Nx cosN NNaN aeoN aNN Noooo cogN ago: N + N mom NNNNV NNN lll<.<¢!d NoNNV oNa NoaooNNooNV NNN N xNozNaoo 305 NNN. V o NNN.NN V S NNN.NN V NN ga>az NNS.N V NNN.NN V N NNN.oN V NN NNN.NN V oN ga>az NNN.NN V Nno. V NNN. V N o o NNN.NN V NNo.NN V NNo.oN V N N N NNN.NN V NNN.NS V NNN.NN V NN oN NN aENm ago: uaugoum mmoNNNmmzou mo muomNzozx NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN. V N N o NNN.NN V NNN.N V NNN. V N N o NNN.N V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N NN NN anm ago: oaNgon NNNNN NNNNNN NzNNNNNN: NoaooNNoooV NNN N NNNzNNNN NN.NN " Nx cosN NNaN aENN aNN Nooo< cozN ago: N + N NNN NaNNV NNN SN.NN u NN :N:N NNaN aENN aNN Nooo< :NNN ago: N + N NNN NaNNV NNN 306 NNN. V NNN.NN V N N NNN.NN V NNN. V oN o NNN.NS V NNN. V NN o ga>az oaoooam NNo.oN V N NNN.NN V N NNN.NN V NN ga>az NNN.NN V NNN. V NNN. V N o o NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.N V N N N NNS.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V oN NN NN anN ago: oaNgoNN m¢m>N¢o zoNznuzoz Nuo. V Nae. V Nae. V o o o NNN.SN V NNN.oN V NNN.NN V N N N NnN.oS V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NS NN NN anm ago: oaNgNNm =NNNNNN. NNNNNNN NSNN NoaSNNNoooV NNN N NNNNNNNN Nm.¢m u Nx :NNN NNaN aeoN aNN Nooo< oocN ago: N + N NNN NNNNV NNN NN.NN u Nx cogN NNaN asoN aoo Noooo cogN ago: N + N mam NNNNV NNN 307 NNN.NN V N NNN.NS V NN NNN.NN V SN ga>az NNN.NN V N NNN. V o Nae. V NNN. V NNN.NN V NNS.NN V NN ga>az NNN.N V NNN.NN V N NNo.oS V oN NNN.NN V NN 95m NNN. V o NNo.oS V oN NNN.SS V NN ago: NNN.NN V N NNN.S V N NNS.SN V NN oaNgoNN mNm>Naz NNN.NN V NNS.NN V NN NNN.NN V oN ga>az NNaN NN.NN V N NNN.N V N NNN. V o NNaN Nae. V Nxo. V Nxo. V o o o NNN.N V NNN.N V NNN.N V N N N NNN.S V NNN.N V NNS.N V N N S asom ago: naugoum mNm>N NNN.NN V NNN. V Nae. V N o o NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN. V N N o NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NN NN NN aeom ago: oaNgon umzumxm mmNmmNaz NNo.oN V NNN.NN V oN NNN.NN V NN N NNo.oN V NNN.N V NNN.NN V NN N omzzo :mNm mo .amm NNN.NN V NNN. V N o NNN.NN V NNN.NN V SN N NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NN oN anm ago: NNN. V o NNS.N V S oaagoNN mozmxwmz zo oz< Nszz N< moN>¢mm NoaSNNNoooV NNN N NNNNNNNN NN.N u N: cocN NNaN aaoN aoN NooNN cogN ago: NcaocaoaooN NNV N N om.NN u Nx cogN NNaN asoN aNN Nooo< cozN ago: N + N NNN NNNNV NNN 310 NNN. V NNo.ooNV o S NNN.SN V NNN.NN V N NN NNN.N V NNN.NN V N NN N N mmoN < N< mszszzm >mmaz aNagom NNNNNN: Nxo3N< 3wzo: oszoN >NN<=NQ< uNmm<¢N mo szummm NNN.NN V NNN. V NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N o o N N NNN.N V NNN.N V NNN.N V NNN.NN V NN.NS V N N N NN NN NNN.N V NNN. V NNo.N V NNN.NS V NNN.SN V N o N NS NN on Noz on gazoN gazoN gazoN gazoN ga>az NNagoa NNNooma NNN3N< NNNNNN oN NNNNN:NN NNNNNNN NNNNNNNNNNN No NNNNNNNNN NoaooNNoooV NNN N NNNNNNNN NN.NN u Nx NNNN NNaN aENN NNN Nooo< cocN ago: NcaocaoaocN NSNV N N No.mN n Nx oogN NNaN asoN aNN Nooo< cogN ago: NcaoeaoaocN NNNV N N mm< 302 mNuaz Nae. V Nxo. V NNN.N V oaoooum NNN.NN V NNN. V NNN. V NNN.NN V N o o N NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.N V NNN.NN V o S N N NNN.N V NNN.N V NNN.NN V NNN.NS V N N oN NS NNaN asom ago: oaagoum NNzaoumNa uNaz NNN.NN V N NNN.NN V SN NNN.NS V NS ga>az NNN. V N NNN. V N NNN.N V N oaoooum NNN. V N NNN. V N NNN.N V N oaooon NNN.NN V NNN. V NNN. V NNN.NN V N N N N NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N N N N NNN.N V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N NN NN NN NNaN asom ago: oaNgon maz NNN.NN V N NNN.NN N NNN.NN V NN ga>az NNN. V NNN. V NNN.NN V N N N NNN.N V NNN.NN V NNS.NS V N S SN NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N NN NN aENm ago: oaNgon :az NNN.N V NNN.NN V N NNS.SN V NN NNN.NNV NS ga>az NNN. V N NNN.N V N NNN.N V N NNaN NNN. V N NNN.N V N NNN. V N NNaN NNN. V N NNN.NN V N NNS.NN V NN asom NNN. V NNS.SN V NN NNN.N V N asom NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N N NNN.NN V NNN.N V N N NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NN SN ago: oaNgoNN m¢u>Nao zoNzauzoz NNN. V NNN.NN V N N NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N S NNS.NN V NNN.NN V NN SN ago: caugoum mNmomma szzosz omNNaz NNN.NN V Nae. V NNN.N V NNaN NNN.NN V N NNN.NN V NN NNN.NN V SN Lw>wz NNN.N V NNN. V NNN.N V NNN. V o oaoooum NNN. V N NNN.N V N NNN.N V N ago: NNN.NN V N NNN.N V N NNN.NN V SN oaNgoNN uzNoNam az NNN.NN V N NNN.NN V N NNN.N V N ga>az NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.NM V NNS.N V NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N N N N NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN.N V N NN N N NNN.N V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNS.NN V N NN NN NN NNaN anm ago: oaNgon NzNNNNN N.N.<.NV NNzN: NNN NNNNNNN NNN. V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V NNN. V N N N N o NN m NNN.N V NNN.NN V NNS.NN V NNN.NN V N SN NN NN NmaN aeom ago: caNgon NNNN NNN N:N:mmzN uzNwz¢m<= zo >mzoz m¥mzoz mmoV mhzmszzm Aom==_a=ouV cap a xVozu¢¢< om.m u Nx cusp mam; memm mgu Vaca< gag» ago: :mmgzm AmHV o a Ho.o~ n Nx cmzh mmmV maum mg“ Vaca< sag» mgoz smmgam A¢VV m a 325 Ago. V o Aao.mV V o Aao.m V N on “oz co Aam.oH V m Axo.mm V ¢V Aao.m~ V e co uoz on Aa~.H V Aam.~ V Aafi.m~ V H N mm Axm.~ V Axm.~a V Anm.~m V H m ma Ago. V Ago. V Ago.¢o V o o ed gaze; Logo; Lmzog Lm>mz apogna a__a:m= Au¢.mm V mm Aum.~m V ma Ano.m~ V N gmzoV mxmx_< =mz apmgmm x__o:m= Aam.o¢ V o¢ Aao.om V ~H Axo.o~ V m gazed mam3_< =VNzNath mNHmz Hngmm xHHmzm: mxmzH< =HHm GHQ 3o: Hum==HH=ouV oz» u xHozNNN< H©.m u Nx can» mmmH 151m 15H Hson< cosh mgoz :mmgsm HeNV NHo oo.cH 1 Nx cmzh mmmH 151m 13H Haoa< can» use: 3cmg=m HHNV HHH 328 HN¢.N V HNH.N V can» mmoH HNN.NN V N cog» mmmH HNN.N V HNN.NN V e NN Han.om V Huo.o¢ V NH NH HNN.N V Ham Hm V N HN «sum osa uaoa< cog» mgo: mm< 3oz mZmpH oz< mmuHmaz NNN.H V NNN.H V HNN.N V NNN.NN V H H N NN NNN. V NNN.NH V NNH.N V NNN.NH V N N N N NNN. V NNN.N V NNN.NH V NNN.N V N N N N oaoooum asom ago: oaugoum NNHNNN mth < szth mazm>mx a >m om¢=maz oaoooum NNN.N V HNN.N V NNN.NN V NNN.NN V N N . NH NN NNN.N V NNN.NH V NNH.N V NNN.NH V H N N N NNN.N V NNN. V NNN.NH V NNN.NN V H N N NH NNaH asom ago: oaugaum HNzNNNNHN NNNNNNNNNV NNN zNszHz NzHNNNzNN NNNNNHNNNNV NNN N NHNzNNNN mm.m~ u Nx cosh NNaH NNNN NNN NNNNN cosh ago: :oagom NNNNV NNN NN.NN 1 Nx cosh NNaH asNN NNN NNNNN cagp ago: :Nagom HNNNV NHNV 332 HNN.NN V NN HNN.NN V NN HNN.HN V NH ga>az NNN.NN V NN HNN.NNHV NN HNN.NN V NH Lm>mz HNN. V HNN. V HNN. V HNN.N V N N N N HNN. V NNH.N V HNN.N V HNN. V N N H N HNN.N V HNN.N V HNN.N V HNN.N V H N N H NNaH asam ago: oaugoum >mm>HHmo mo >az HNN.NH V NNN. V HNN. V HNH.NH V HNN.NN V N o N HH NN HNN.HN V HNN.N V HNN.N V NNN.NH V HNN.NN V NH H N N NH HNN.NH V HNN. V HNN. V HNN.NH V HNN.NN V N N N N NH ga>az NNaH asom ago: oaugaam muHaaz HNN.N V N HNN.NH V N HNN. V N NNNN HNN.NH V NH HNN.N V H HNN. V N ago: HNN.NH V NH HNN.N V N HNN.NN V N caugoam >hHaozh=< wzHuHmm m>az NNaH HNN.NH V NH NNN.NN V N HNN.N V H anm HNN.NN V NN HNN.NH V N HNN.N V H ago: NNN.NH V NH HNN.NH V N NNN.NN V N NNNLNNN mpmomma manomHzm wsz: Aonh<>ozzHV HoaNNNNNooV ozN N xHNzNNN< 9H.md u Nx cog» NNaH NNNN NNN NNNNN cock ago: oaagom HNNNV NNN mo.m~ u Nx cosh NNaH asam azu uaon< cosh ago: :oagom HNNNV NNN. HoaNNNNNNNV NNN N xHNzNNNN 335 HNN.NN V NN HNN.NN V NN HNN.NN V NH ga>az HNH.N V HNN.HN V HNN.NN V ga>az HNN.H V H HNN.N V N HNN. V N NNaH HNN.N V N HNN. V N HNN. V N NNaH NNN.N V HNN.NN V NH HNN.NN V NH NN.NH V asom NNH.NH V NH HNN.N V H HNN. V o ago: HNN.NH V NH HNN.NH V N HNN.NN V N NNNgNHN muHmm mHmomm mmHaz NNaH HNN.NH V N HNN.NH V N HNN.NN V N gm>mz HNN.NN V HN HNN.NN V NH NN.NH V N OEwm HNN.HH V HNN.N V NH N HNN.N V HNN.NH V N N HNN.NN V HNN.NH V N N Ngox oaNNNNN mmmxmoz HHma caz HNH.N V HNN.NN V HNN.NN V ga>az Ago. V HNN.N V HNN. V oaoooom HNN.NH V NH HNN.NN V HH HNN.NN V N asom HNN.N V HNH.NN V N NN HNN.N V HNN.NN V N NH HNN.N V HNN.NN V N NH ago: oaugoum NzHuHam meow NHN HNN.NN V HNN.NN V NN NN HNN.NN V HNN.N V NH N HNN.NN V HNN.NN V N N ago: oaagoum mHm>Haz Ago. V HNN.NN V N NN HNN. V HNN.NN V N NH HNN.N V HNN.N V H N NNaH anm HNN.NN V HNN.NN V NN NN HNN.NH V HNN.NH V N N HNN.NH V HNN.NN V N HH ago: oaugoum onp<>ozzH muH>awmxmonm cszmmwwam zH oaz HNN. V HNN.NH V N NH HNN.N V HNN.NN V H N HNN. V HNN. V N N NNaH asom HNN.NH V HNN.HH V NH NH HNN.N V HNN.N V N H HNN.N V HNN.NN V N N ogoz NNNNNNN mmzmmxm zuHmmHaz HNN.N V HNN.NN V NH HNN.NN V ga>az HNN.H V H HNN.N V H HNN. V o oaoooum HNN.N V N HNN. V N HNN. V N NNaH HNN.H V H HNN. V N HNN.N V H NNaH HNN.NN V HNN.NN V NNN.NN V NN NN NN HNN.NN V NNN.NN V HNN.NH V N HH N HNN.N V HNN.NH V HNN.NN V H N NH agom ago: oaogoom NzHNHNN H.N.<.NV NNzHN HNN NNNHNNN HNH.NH V HNN.HN V HNH.NN V NH NN NN HNN.NN V HNN.NN V HNN.NH V NH NH N HNN.NH V HNN.NN V HNN.NN V N N NH anm ago: naugoum NNNNN NHNNNNNNNN NNN HoaNNNNNNNV NNN N xHNzNNNN NH.NN 1 Nx cocp NNaH NNNN NNN NNNNN cocp ago: :oagom HzNNV NNN mN.¢~ u Nx cocp NNaH NNNN NNN NNNNN cocp ago: ooagom HNNNV NNN ,xcchNccoV ozp N xHNzNNNN fif/(/ 340 HNN.N V N HNN.N V N HNN.N V H amnesmH HNN.N V HNN.NH V HNN. V o NN-NNNH HNH.NN V NN HNN.NN V NN HNN.NN V NH ga>az HNN.NH V N HNN.N V N HNN.NH V N mmuommH HNH.N V Ago. V Hue. V NNaH HNN.NH V NH HNN.NN V N HNN.NN V N mouoemH HNN.NN V NH HNN.NH V HNN.N V H anm HNN.NN V NN HNN.NH V N HNN.NH V N HNN.NN V NH HNN.NN V NH HNN.NN V HH omnommH ommH agomam amaznom >z