‘!ESIS 0W LIBRARY Michigan State University Wrmflrm‘r PART IV THE LAND REFORM PROGRAM AND ITS IMPLEMENTATION INTRODUCTION: Emergence and Acceleration of the Contra- diction, attempt for Distruction of Feudalism, and Introduction of the Capitalist Relations of Production in Agriculture In peripheral social formation, there are different class contradictions. In each period, one of these contradictions becomes the main one. It is important to recognize the main contradiction in each are of the society under consideration. Because of the nature of the state in Iran before the World War II, the basic contradiction in the society was a contradiction between the people and the ruling classes and their alliance (i.e., feudals, dependent bourgeois, and foreign investors). Other contradictions were between feudals and bourgeois, foreign capital and feudalism, and between foreign capitalists over the issue of controlling Iran's economy. After the War, as a result of the constant defeat of the people and their suppression, the contradiction between people and the ruling classes was reduced. On the other hand, dependent bourgeoisie were expanding both qualitatively and quantitatively; feudalism was declining because of a series of historical events; and finally, United States 263 investment gained ascendancy over British investment in Iran. Consequently, the contradiction between the dependent bourgeoisie and its ally (U.S. capitalism ) on the one side, and feudalism and its old ally (British capita- lsim), on the other side, became the basic contradiction of the Post-War era. it this stage the dependent bourgeoisie, because of its nature, must sweep any obstacles to its expansion. In the same way, because of the nature of the relation between center and periphery, the foreign investors perceived feudalism as the prime barrier for their further and still deeper penetration into the Iranian economy. It is in relation to these characteristics of the dependent bourgeoisie and foreign capital that the action of the land reform as a means to eradicate the feudal relations bf production must 'be analyzed. If the aim of the dependent bourgeoisie and foreign investors was to eXpand their activities in the agrarian sector of the society, and if the means to achieve this aim was the land reform, then, the principles of the program K must be designed in harmony with expansion of the capitalist relations of production and institutions in the countryside. It is in relation to this notion that the Iranian land reforl laws and regulations will be examined. In addition, the implementation of the reform is crucial to our understandings of the hidden objectives of the land reform. The results of the distribution and establishment of the new institutions 264 will be taken into consideration in order to build up a case for further steps toward analyzing the effects of the reform on the rural social class structure. CHAPTER ELEVEN PUDH FOR LAND REFORM 11.i. Introduction There are several explanations for the cause of land reform in Iran (see chapter one). An attempt shall be made here to construct a meaningful and objective explanation of the land reform movement in Iran. One thing certain here is that the conflict over the political and economic nature of the government was intense during the 1941-1961 period. It was in this period that different efforts for the implementation of land reform were suggested by different groups. The Shah was by no means the first person to call for land reform in Iran. Land reform in Iran has a long history dating back to the beginning of present century. Different revolutionary and nationalist groups have attempted to enforce land reform in one way or another. On the other hand, different cabinets of the Pahlavi regime have touched the issue in different times. Although the 1962 land reform was carried out by the Shah, it was not his genuine idea and will. On the contrary, it was a result of the main contradiction which existed at that period of time in Iran. The aim of this chapter is chiefly to find the cause of 266 the 1962 land reform through the main contradiction in Iranian society. For this purpose, I have to give a back- ground to different land reform attempts at different times. As a result, land distribution ideas and activities in Iran could be classified in three categories: (1) the early "democratic” ideas and attempts on land distribution; (2) distribution of Crown and Public domain lands; and (3) the 1962 land reform. 11.2. The Early "Democratic" Ideas and Attempts From the Constitutional Revolution of 1905-1911 to the immediate post—Mussadiq years at least seven movements were directed at the modification of the property relationship between the landlord and the peasants, restructuring the proprietary order in some parts of the country. Land reform was recommended publicly as early as the Constitutional Revolution. It was one of the principles of the Mujahed Social Democrat society of Mashhad, established in 1907. In their program, they mentioned the confiscation of the king's and the big khans' lands on behalf of the peasantry. In addition, they mentioned the limitation of land property for all other landowners (Nik-Aein, 1980:47). Land redistribution was one of the policies of the Democratic Party, formed in 1909 by reform-minded deputies of the Second Majlis. However, the members of the party were only a minority within the Majlis; therefore, chances to test their many ideas for reform were limited (Bahar, 1942:5). 267 The Democratic Party did not achieve its land reform goal through the Majlis. During World War I, some Iranians recently returned from the Caucasus province of the Soviet Union, where they had worked for several years in the Baku oil fields, formed the Communist Party (Zabih, 1966). At the same time, some Democrats organized a major guerrilla campaign against the foreign occupation in the province of Gilan. The guerrilla force became known as the Jangali movement. The Communists, influenced by the revolutionary experi— ences they had witnessed in Russia believed that one of their tasks was the expropriation for distribution of all large estates (i.e., state, religious, crown, and private lands) in the country. They put this task in their party's program (Nik-Aein, 1980:48). On the other hand, the Jangalis were closely involved with the peasants, and they believed in many reforms such as increasing the share-cropper's portion of the harvest, lightening the labor services, abolishing the dues in kind, and forcing the wealthy collaborators to distribute some of their estates among the peasantry (Kazemi, 1978:285). The Communists joined the Jangalis and established the Gilan Soviet Socialist Republic. In this coalitional government, the Communitsts were determined to implement radical land redistribution; while the founder of the Jagalis, Mirza Kuchek Khan, supported reforms aimed at improving the conditions of the peasants, and it seemed he had opposed any 268 general concept of land redistribution (Ibid., P.286). Internal contradictions soon broke the United front apart. At the same time, the forces of the new central government, WhiCh was at odds With the. movement, over the. issue of their separatism, entered Gilan and suppressed the movement and most of the rural reforms it had instituted were undone (Hooglund, 1982:38-39). In 1941, some of the Iranian Marxists organized a Marxist party, the Tudeh (Masses). While successfully organizing the urban workers, the party also tried to appeal to the rural masses. Its official program called for the immediate distribution of state and crown lands among the peasants; the gradual buying of large private estates by the state and their sale at low interest rates to the landless peasantry; and the retention of a larger share of the harvest by the sharecrOppers (Nik-Aein, 1980:49). The party formed a Peasant Union and sent workers and students into the countryside to organize the villagers. The party's appeals to the peasants failed. The Tudeh was unable to attract any significant following among the peasantry. Since the party was never in a position to exercise real political power, its professed dedication to the cause of rural reform was never put to a test. In trying to explain these failures, one party leader years later argued the ‘the party had lacked cadres with rural backgrounds able to speak the same languages and dialects as the peasants, to under- stand their needs, to voice their demands, and, thereby, 269 accomplish the difficult task of mobilizing them, into viable organizations (Kambakhsh, 1968:32). One may argue that this was not the case, since there were some structual problems with Iranian peasantry in comparison to Russian or Chinese peasantry (Cf. Kazemi, 1978). Another Marxist group, the Firqah-i Dimukrat-i Azarbayjan, grasped control over Azarbayjan province and established an autonomous regime in that province in November of 1945. In April 1946, the provincial government prepared a land reform law which allow for the distribution of state land to the peasant. In relation to the landlords' estates, the leaders of the revolutionary government compromised with the local Azarbayjani landlords and confiscated only the estates which belonged to non—native owners (Gharatchedaghi, 1967:37-38). The Firqah-i Dimukrat, like the Jangali movement, was suppressed in December 1946. Subsequently, their land reform legislation was abrogated. One clarification is needed here before I go further on the issue of democratic land reform ideas and attempts.The above-mentioned cases were ones in which land distribution - was decided on by a revolutionary grouping then in power, and they were not in the first instance results of the demands of a peasant movement. After the Second World War, some independent intellec- tualls sympathetic to leftist ideology (i.e., Hassan Arsanjani) were interested in the land reform issue. Their concerns about rural reform did not originate solely from ideology but 270 also from a genuine dislike for the existing agrarian system. They became convinced that a reformation of the land tenure system was the necessary prerequisite for ending the poverty and exploitation of the peasantry. Their main efforts were in the form of suggestions to the government. However, since they had neither an organizational base nor a voice in the government, their suggestions were useless. The National Front, a place for nationalistic-reformist intellectualls, had emerged in 1949 under the leadership of Dr. Mahammad Musaddiq. By March 1951 they had become a politically strong enough force to appoint Musaddiq as a prime minister. Two decrees were issued by him in October 1952. The first stipulated that following division of the crop, 20 per cent of the landlord‘s share was to be returned to the village; 10 per cent would be distributed among the sharecroppers and 10 per cent would be reserved for village development projects. The second decree abolished free labor service and all the various dues which landlords customarily levied upon their sharecroppers.1 In May 1955,,Musaddiq suspended the sale of the Crown lands by the Shah and instituted action designed to transfer title of these lands to the state (wiiber, 1965:182). Musaddiq’s effort was insubstantial becuase it lacked a redistribution of the large landowner's estates. Part or the reasons for his failure lay in the very nature of his government. _h August 1955, Musaddiq was deposed in a coup d'etat through the financial support of interested foreign 271 powers, particularly the United States. Finally, 1 should mention here the last democratic program put forward by a member of the leadership of the second National Front, Khalil Maleki. He offered a proposal for the democratization or popularisation (melli Kardan) of land and water. Maleki's program was as follows: to transfer the title of ownership from the landlords to the peasant community as a whole, which would dispossess the landlords at a stroke and without complicated legal and other wrangles; avoid the colossal administrative task of defining every single peasant-holding in every village; prevent the emergence of scattered and small individual hoidings; and bypass the immediate problem of dispossessing the landless community.2 The idea was too advanced and too radical for it to be under- stood by any political force in the country. Nalek"s program would work only as part of the construction of a broader and genuinely democratic society; it was part of his vision of Iranian socialism. What is important to say here is that all these democra- tic ideas and attempts were suppressed either in their embryo- nic stages or at the middle of their implementation by the central government which was a supporter of the landowning class. The government by no means was a supporter of the peasants in Iran. 272 11.5. Distribution of Crown and Public Domain Lands from the beginning of the Pahlavi's era, a number of ineffective efforts for redistribution of Public Domain lands were put forward by the government. In addition to this, since 1941 Mohammad Reza Shah attempted to sell the crown lands several times in the name of the redistribution of the crown lands to the peasants. During the rule of Reza Shah, a few superficial attempts were made to distribute the state lands, but theseaefforts were ill-formed and did not bear any positive effect. These efforts resulted simply in the usurpation of state lands by the big and influential landowners. From 1927 to 1941, the governmental attempts to redistribute Khaliseh land in Sistan, Khuzestan, Luristan, Kirmanshah and Dasht-i Moghan, were unsuccessful. As Lambton has indicated: Where land has in fact been distributed, it has either never got into the hands of the peasant proprietors or, where it has, they have been subjected to pressure of various kinds and it due course have been expropriated in many cases (1955:244). In September, 1941, under the pressure of the national opposition, Mohammed Reza Shah ceded the Crown Lands, confiscated by his father, to the state. In 1942 a law was passed providing for the return of a number of these estates to their original owners (Rudulph, 1971:51). Some of the lands were given back to the original owners. However, the Shah soon noticed that the government was using the revenues from the Crown land to meet its ordinary expenses. After some deliberation, he decided to take back the lands and 273 to sell them. As a result, in July 1949, under the pressure ofthe Shah, the Najlis passed a bill providing that all lands that had not been successfully reclaimed were to revert to the possession of the Shah. In January 1951 the Shah issued a decree providing for the sale of his 2,000 villages to the peasants. The sale proceeded very gradually over a ten-year period, and fully one-third of the royal lands were sold to various wealthy favorites of the Shah, rather than to peasants (Hooglund,1982: 45). As I mentioned before, during Dr. Musaddiq's premiership, the Shah's effort to sell the crown lands was stopped for a time by order of the government. But the sale resumed after the fall of Musaddiq. Within the decade 1953-62, some 517 villages were sold (Mclachlan, 1968:692). During this period, the Shah turned many of the remaining lands over to his brothers and sisters. He kept a large proportion of the remaining land for himself and his son. It was in this period that the Pahlavi families started to become the big agri- cultural capitalists of the country (Nik—Aein, 1980: 42). After an abortive attempt at redistribution of the Public Domains, further distribution of Public Domain took place under the provisions of the 1955 law for the distribution of Public Domains through the country (McLachlan, 1968:691). The law was only implemented in 1958 and had a very limited impact. This distribution of the Khales h villages eventually was caught up in the land reform of 1962. During the 1962 274 land reform the entire khaleseh village were distributed. To sum up this section, I should mention here that it has been recorded that, during the state land distribution, in.many cases by interfering with the distribution of water, and by withholding water, the land of the peasants became valueless. As a result, the peasants were thus forced to sell out at a low price or merely abandoned the land, which was then usurped (Cf. Lambton, 1955:252). On the other hand, most of the Crown lands were sold to wealthy friends of the Shah who later established large-scale mechanized capitalist farming. 11.4. Causes of the 1962 Land Reform In the first half of the present century, the major foreign investment was confined to the Iranian oil industry. But, as we know, in the period after 1950 a new form of domination, known.as the New Dependency, characterized the development of peripheral countries in general(Dos Santos, 1970). As is well known, this period corresponded to a new phase in world capitalist expansion, whereby mutinational corporations started to take over the economy of Third World nations. Since the Second World War the U.S. had increased its influence in Iran through supporting the regime. During the 1950's American policy in Iran was focused on creating internal security and stability through military strength, as well as economic growth. The first American act was the 1953 coup d'etat. (Cf. Nirumand, 1969:25). 275 After the coup, it was obvious to the Americans that the Shah would be able to guarantee the internal stability of the country along the lines of their policy only if they accorded him massive financial and military support from the very outside. The initial $45 million arrived in Iran as early as September 15,1955, to be followed by another $15.5 million a few months later; U.S. aid totalled $127,3 million for the fiscal year 1954 (Nirumand, 1969:93). After these aids, Iran became a testing ground for the deveIOpment of political and economic structures aimed at keeping the Third World under the domination of the capitalism of the center (Holfgott, 1976:22). Since then, Iran's development, engineered in Washington, has moved in the direction of greater political and economic power in the hands of the Shah and the expanding dependent bourgeoisie. The social order andsecurity, which were maintained by the use of absolute force in this period, were partially designed to attract both domestic and foreign capital for investment. Following the coup of 1955, for the first time, the private sector was granted an Opportunity to grow rapidly. As Ashraf indicated: The most interesting and significant indus- trial development of the 1950s was the emergence of an private sector on a much larger scale than anyone had expected (1971:255). During this time, the Shah insisted that future public enterprises be limited to a few branches of heavy industry and that the government carry even these only as far as 276 the preparatory steps, when presumably private enterprise might take them over (Clawson,1977:69). At the same time, the Shah invited the foreign inves- tors to invest in Iranian economy. As the Shah stated during his 1958 visit to Washington, D.C.: Iran is on the eve of its greatest development. Its economic potentialities and the scope for foreign capital investment is unlimited...Now is the time for bold, imaginative measures on the part of American private capital to come into Iran and join the prodigious efforts we are making. The present opportunity may not present itself again (queted in Silsby,1980:56). In addition, the enactment of the Law Concerning the Attrac- tion and Protection of Foreign capital in Iran in 1955 opend up the Iranian economy to Western capitalism in general and to the American corporations in particular (Walton, 1980:275). As a result of this law, up to June 1958 some 1084 foreign compaines were established in Iran in different sectors of the economy, but very few in the agricultural sector (Ivanovgn.d.:195). In relation to this new type of dependency, the feudal system of production imposed a static type of relationship in rural areas, and this was diametrically opposed to the interests and modern design of the dependent bourgeoisie and foreign capitalists who wanted to expand their activities. Feudalism in Iran was acceptable to the hour- geoisie of the center as long as the center/ periphery relationship was confined to the extraction of raw materials, the limited importation of consumer goods, and the 277 exportation of capital. Since the relation between Iran's economy and the center entered a new phase, the bourgeoisie of the center in collaboration with the Iranian dependent bourgeoisie had to disslove precapitalist forms in the economy and politics of Iran, molding traditional oppression by the indigenous exploitative classes with the needs of Capital to produce a new structure and process. As such, "the destruction of the feudal mode of production was placed on the agenda of the dependent bourgeoisie/ imperiah list axis as the most urgent task of the day" (Forouzin, 1979:147). The rise of dependent bourgeois activities had shown the ruling families and landowners that the traditional landowning enterprise was becoming outmoded and uneconomical and thus, declining as compared with the flourishing opportunities in business enterprises. Some of the land- owners recognized this opportunity and shifted to bourgeois activities.3 Among them the Shah himself sold the land at his own prices, and put the funds into very good use both inside and outside the country, ridding himself of dangerous immovable property, and boasting to the whole world that he was giving 'his own' lands back to the peasants (Katouzian,1981:500). As Pesaran has indicated: Almost all major industrialists in.the private sector were hand-picked for their loyalty to the ‘Pahlavi regime and were backed by members of the royal family and the court either directly or indirectly through the machinery of the Pahlavi Foundation (1982:510). 278 But, the majority of the landowning class resisted any drastic change in village communities. 0n the other hand, they did not show any interest in selling any piece of their land because land was the source of their socio- politico-economic power. Despite the activities of the dependent bourgeoisie in the agriculture of the Gorgan and Dasht regions, the existence of the precapitalist agricultural system and the type of ownership of land was an obstacle to further development of dependent bourgeois activities in agriculture. In addition to the dependent bourgeoisie, the foreign cor- porations wanted to invest directly on a large scale in the agricultural sector. A contradition arose here between the interests of the dependent bourgeoisie and foreign capital on one side, and feudal landlords on the other side. To overcome the contradiction, American capitalism perceive feudalism as the prime obstacle for its further and still deeper penetration into the Iranian economy. "Following the newly formulated policy of 'social reform'... the United States exercised a massive pressure on the ruler of Iran to innovate reform policies and implement a land reform program" (Ashraf, 1971:132) with an almost missonary zeal as a panacea to developmental problems in Iran. AS an American adviser to the Plan Organization clearly pointed out: The attempt to extend land distribution beyond the Shah's Crown Land program was mainly an American objective (Baldwin,1967:93). 279 The Kennedy administration immediately set up a task force for this purpose. The American ambassador to Tehran, Armin Meyer, recently revealed: "That task force did nothing but work on Iran. The idea was that Iran's demise was about to take place... that it was about to go down the drain, and we just had to take some dramatic and drastic steps" (Kayhan International,1977). In the beginning the Shah was hesitant and resisted Kennedy's persuasians, which, as time went by, evolved into open threats. The United States' Administration threatened to withdraw a 55 million dollar loan from the already recession-shocked economy (Halliday, 1979:44-5). A180, miliary aid to the vulnerable shah became dependent on the implementation of land reform. When in 1960, the attempted coup of General Gharani was discovered, the Shah realized the gravity of the situation. At this time, the American support of the Shah was conditioned by appointing Ali Amini, who was assumed to carry out the necessary process of land reform, as prime minister of Iran.4 The Shah could not afford to ignore American advice. By selecting Amini to head his government, the Shah hoped to demonstrate that his ideas and goals for Iran were similar to those of Iran's principal foreign ally. In this regard, the Shah had to alienate the feudal landlords in order to pave the road for his new alliance the dependent bourgeoisie. This was not an easy task for the Shah, because he partially owed his Crown to the feudalists who persist tently sabotaged the progressive measures of Dr. Musaddiq 280 and conspired to their utmost to mar his efforts, and who constituted the main social basis of the 1955 coup d'etat. The Shah was aware that his espousal of the land reform program still involved a serious risk to his position: land- lords and other conservative forces would not give up with- out a struggle. However, the Shah accepted any risk to strengthen his position since he thought the successful land reform would change the economic and political power of the landowning class vis-a—vis the rising bureaucracy and bourgeoisie. As Ashraf has indicated, A community of interest has been established between the higher echelon of bureaucracy and the economic elites. Without the coalition with these elements, the wealthy bourgeoisie would lose its power and probably its prosperity (1970:351). In fact, this shift was as a result of both the internal and external pressures on the Iranian regime. Some measures were taken before the initiation of the land reform in order to safeguard its implementation. 0n the one hand, Amini brought along Hassan Arsanjani as his Minister of Agriculture and gave him responsibility for developing a policy for land reform. This action was taken to divert people's mind from the nature of the land reform, since Arsanjani had a good reputation among the people for having excellent ideas of land reform (Richards,1975:6-7). 0n the other hand, the Shah dissolved the Majlis and closed the Senate in 1961. He dissolved both houses of parliament because they were dominated mostly by the landlords' 281 interests and he did not want to see emasculation of this last land reform law. After Parliament was dissolved, the previous Land Reform Law was amended by a cabinet decree approved by the Council of Ministers on January 9,1962. To sum up, although in this period the landowners were socially, politically, and economically powerful and shared in state decisionpmaking, they began to ebb when dependent bourgeoisie started to become economically and politically strong in the society. The international situation between peripheral and core countries created a situation in which foreign supporters of the landowners could not continue their support. Landowners were forced to concede their prominent status to leaders of the dependent bourgeoisie who had more flexibility in generating surplus. In fact, the kind of reform carried out in Iran was a faithful reflection of the interplay of alliances and conflicts that have arisen between the dominant classes: the land- owning nobility, the merchant bourgeoisie of the "bazar", the imperial family and new dependent bourgeoisie, along ‘ with their British and American allies. It was a product of the capitalist character of the Iranian state. 282 1. 3. 4. 11.5.Endnotes For further information see Lambton's Persian Land Reform, 1969. pp. 57-38. See his various articles in issues of Ilm va Zindigi (monthly periodical) 1959-62, and Firdowsi (WeekIy magazine) 1962. A glimpose into the class composition of the emerging bourgeoisie illustrates that the landowners constituted 50 per cent of farm.capitalists in the Gorgan region (Ashraf,1971:181). Amini had previously served as Iran's ambassador to Wahington, and had special ties with the Kennedys (Saikal, 1980:76). 283 CHAPTER TWELVE THE 1962 LAND REFORM AND ITS IMPLEMENTATION 12.1. Introduction What is known as Land Reform in Iran consisted of a series of acts beginning with a bill dated 12/31/1961 which was approved by the Cabinet in the absence of parliament. The reform attempted to transfer the ownership of the large holdings as well as some tenancy reform. With regard to these two aims three distinct phases could be seen during the decade in.which the transfer of land ownership and re-organization of the relations of production took place. Three major efforts were being made with respect to re-organization of relations of production. In the phase one, attempts were made to establish rural cooperative societies. Membership in these societies was a prerequisite for obtaining the distributed land. In phase two of the reform, the landlord and the peasant were encouraged to establish a joint-stock farming unit. Finally, in the phase three, the government design.was to create large-scale agriculture through either farm corporations or large agri- businese enterprise. The actual task of executing the laws of the land reform was the responsiblility of the specially created Land Reform Organization (later the Ministry of Cooperative and 284 Rural Affairs). This task was hard because the land owner- ship in Iran was involved with political power. Its imple- mentation became harsh since the Land Refom Organization faced a severe reaction from the landowning class and other reactionary groups. As a result, the land reform program was affected by these reactions, and there was some modification in its original plan. However, the land reform reached its aims gradually. The task of this chapter is to provide the content of the different laws as well as the nature of them. In addition, the statistical results of the distribution of the land will appear here too. It is important to distinguish between lands that were incorporated into the "reform" and "nonreform" sectors in.the process of land reform. The reform sector is compsed of lands appropriated from the former landlords and sold out to the peasants. The nonpreform sector includes the unexpropriated lands retained by their former owners, the lands that were legally or illegally exempted from the distribution. Because of the nature of the land reform, the relations of production in both sectors were changed drastically. It was these laws and the supplementary related measures that changed the social structure in the rural areas of Iran. Study of the effects of these laws and measures on the socio- economic structure of the rural communities is the intention‘ of part V of this dissertation. 12.2. The Laws Governing the First Phase This section consist of two parts: first the law 285 regarding the distribution of the lands; and second, the regulation of the establishment and membership of the rural cooperative societies. The law governing the first phase of the land reform was drawn up and approved by the Council of Ministers and the Shah in the absence of the Majlis after its prorogation in 1961 (McLachlan, 1968:692). The aim was the distribution of large holdings belonging to absentee land-owners, and the limitation of individual land-ownership. The main elements of the law regarding the distribution of the land in phase one were as follows: 1) limitation of the size of individual holdings to six dangs (equal to one whole village); landlords were required to sell their excess holdings to the government. It was optional for them to choose which village to retain; in addition, the landlords were allowed to keep the equivalent of one whole village scattered among a number of villages (McLachlan, 1968:693). 2) to arrange the price of land which was taken from landlords and redistributed among the peasants. Compensation was based on the landlord's average tax payment in the most recent year multiplied by a coefficient calculated separately for each region. This coefficient was to vary between 102 and 180, depending on a variety of factors: the recency of the local land tax assessment, the local practice of crop division between landlord and tenant, the distance from market, etc. (Research Group, 1970:7). 3) to allocate holdings among the peasants without changing the existing field layout of the village (Azkia, 1980:52). 4) membership in a rural cooperative was necessary for the peasants who were eligible to receive land (Research Group,1970). 286 5) to redistribute the lands among those peasants‘ who were naggq-holder. In instances where the land had been assigned to a ggggh, rather than to the individual pasag-holder, the members would divide the bupgh's field among themselves (Hooglund,1980:54). The above mentioned regulations precluded any need for a comprehensive survey on land ownership and nasaq-holders and speeded up the redistribution. In each village it was clear who was nasaqfholder and who did not have such a right. Nevertheless, inevitable inequalities would result as a consequence of the criteria of nasaqgholding. The land reform law, instead of providing any particular new arrangements for the division of the waters of qanats, rivers or wells, indicated that this shall be done on the basis of the traditional common law practice of the locality. It was arranged that the ownership of the qanats should be given over to the peasants jointly, the rights of each being based on )the traditional rights attached to a parti- cular piece of land. In the case of rivers, the respective traditional water rights of each piece of land should be transferred to the peasant (Research Group,1970:72). Theoretically, supervision of the water resources of the transferred lands, and the upkeep and repair of irrigation channels were to be the responsibility of the relevant co- operative society (Lambton, 1969:275). In practice, this arrangement caused trouble in the first phase of the reform. According to the laws of phase one, lands which were in principle to be made exceptions to the reform, apart from the six-dang of ownership,1 were defined as follows: 287 a) Fruit orchards, tea groves and nurseries, the land and standing property (a'yan) of which belonged to the landlord. b) Mechanized agricultural lands, that is, estates which at the date of promulgation of the land reform law, were farmed by mechanized equipment and without the labor of share-croppers (Parham,1971:105) c) Estates which were made into private endowments (Vaqf-i khas) before 6/12/59. d) All the ublic endowed lands (Vaqf amm) (Denman, 1978:265g. ‘—_' "_' I will explain later how some of these exemptions became barriers to the redistribution of lands among the peasants. The second most important aspect of the initial phase of the land reform was the development of the rural coopera- tives. The rural cooperative societies in Iran date back to 1955 when rural fund societies were established. The land reform law of 1962 gave greater impetus to the expansion of cooperatives since those who drafted the law intended the cooperative movement to be widespread, with these societies taking the place of the landowner in the villages which were transferred to peasants. In fact, they were the product of state policies during late 19503 and early 19608. These societies were expanded in rural areas, as an incorporated part of the first phase of the reform. Theoretically, a simple logic was to rule the distribu- tion: no cooperative, no distributed land (Denman,1978:280). The Note to Article 16 of the Land Reform Law stated that land shall be given to peasants who have already joind the co-operative society of their district, and the 18th session of the Land Reform Council dated 6/3/62 placed a restriction 288 on membership by saying that only those who were to receive land under the terms of the land reform were eligible to join the co-operative society (Research Group,1970:71). In fact membership in the rural cooperatives was made mandatory for peasants receiving land; and was forbidden for landless peasants. The land reform organization assumed that cooperatives would provide credit and also general supervision and direction of agricultural affairs, i.e., to obtain and distribute seeds, seedlings, and purebred livestock. Further- more, the task was to facilitate agricultural marketing, and to promote modern farming in the region. One should expect the high speed of quantitative expansion of these societies, while at the same time questioning the quality of them. What was really important for the Land Reform Organization was the numberical existence of these societies. This affected the function of these societies; and as a result they became a tool for putting the peasant proprietors in a disastrous situation rather than filling the gap which resulted from the absence of the landlords. 12.3. The Implementation and the Results of the First Phase The land reform officals suggested a district-by- district approach to implementation of the reform. The area around the city of Maragheh in East Azarbayjan province was selected as a pilot case for putting the reform into effect. Thus, as early as March 1962, the first series of lands were transfered to the peasants (Lambton,1969:90). After buying 289 the land, the government immediately resold it to the peasants for the purchase price plus a maximum 10 per cent charge for administrative costs. Payments were arranged into fifteen equal installments due annually at harvest time. This was, in theory, a uniform practice for the whole country. As Denman has indicated, there was no rural land market in Iran, and no market price of land or villages to which compesation could be related (1978:267). For the whole country, the average price of the purchased villages was some 540,000 rials (approximately $ 7,000), which seems somewhat lower than the real value of the villages. This was attributed to the fact that the landholdings were valued on the basis of taxes paid by the owners, and since most f of the influential landlords had for years evaded payment ( of taxes on their land, they suffered losses (Research F Group, 1964a: 145-6). Although it seems from the above paragraph that the landlords were mostly the losers, they managed in fact to find numberous ways of getting around the laws. Many of them were able to preserve some of their land, either by taking I f various kinds of evasive measures, or by complying with the stipulated exemption conditions. As a result, a great ; number of landlords passed their lands off as mechanized. To fl strengthen their case, they sometimes put a tractor on their u farm and dug an artesian well. On other occasions they would revoke the existing peasant-landlord relationship and would employ the peasants as laborers, thereby giving them the status of farm-workers. "At least 1180 villages 290 were exempted as mechanized villages“ (Halliday,1979:111). The landlords were able to do that because there was no clear definition of the term "mechanized estate" in the original law. As I explained before, the definition of a landlord by the Higher Council of the land reform was irrespective of the age and status of the owner. Many of the landlords responded to this situation by redistributing their villages among their wives, children and relatives. This was the easiest and chepest way for them to escape the redistribution since they were able to backdate documents with the help of private registrars; or rearrange the pages of the official registration books (GOPF,1976:51). Many landlords bribed reform officials and thus retained some of their land that legally they were no longer entitled to.2 Also, the fact that scattered plots from different villages totalling to a whole-village could be retained by the landlord made it possible for-the landlord to select the best parcels, in terms of quality, from a number of villages and at the same time maintain his influence as the biggest free-holder in each village. ‘ All the above mentioned ways of escaping the redis- tribution of the land limited the degree to which land has been distributed, but at the same time they bring about these developments in agriculture which the reform was designed to encourage. They were contrary to an egalitarian principle of land-to-the-tiller, but not to the development of capitalism in the countryside. 291 IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII---::———————————————* The weakening of government implementation continued for serveral years during the competion of the first phase of the land reform. By 1965, the number of purchased villages had reached 12,920, of which only 9,888 had been given out among 432,043 peasants (Sazaman-i islahat-i arzi, 1966:5). Some of these results are summarized in Table 12.1. out of 432,043 families who acquired land in the first phase, a relatively small number (perhaps about 50 to 40 per cent) have acquired lands in acounts of between 1 and 2 hectares. The rest have been given a negligible amount that could not possible support them (GOPF, 1976:35). Some of these villages had the least land, the least water, and were the least fertile; they were, in short, the worst of their kind, since the landlords had the choice to choose the best lands. Execution of the first phase was not uniform in the different provinces of the country, due to the different systems of landownership and differences in the power of local landlords. The fastest rate in the early months was in the province of Fare (56% of 2,794 village had been trans— ferred to the Government), and little happened at all in Baluchestan (1%) and Yazd (0%) (Richards, 1975:7). Although the first phase succeeded in redistributing land and breaking the power of the major landlords, yet the number of villages directly affected by the first phase constituted only a small proportion of the total number of villages in the country (about 20%). The overall impact of the reform was by no means small, as the large land holdings of all major landlords were liquidated, with profound socio-political 292 .ortm “moor .asum slamsmamfl filamsmsmm "meadow reed? 03.2 m8? $3 .32: sees 8 we 8 a sea 5:83 Ban 8 ee 3 new 82 new asses 33... see as. 8 2e.” . assesses: Seam $3 in a: $3 7:2 .535 asset note: 83: 2? a? an aces sass: amen: 3e 2n 3 85 assess emu; at; as .2 one; censuses and :3 :5.— s: :3: sensors 89% BS 23 :m :3 assessments Sum one we... me name nests meson Sm a... 8 _ Se nears 3.8 fie new 8— see; 58.5: me e e e 5 53:0 a; 2 2 m nee 32 5.80 no :20 memes as new as are 5:0 ages 33 23 an. echo sea mm... as 8 ea mesa seam see canteen owns: see e8 e2 83 essences... to? Rape $3 on: «an ease 523:3 can pee.— mfizoouz .38. mcmfiév meant 22o: «Essa 02:65 3:835" _ omen—a .3 nausea: acme—.5 use mowfiz> . -e.mthM.uoeq n noseafldnnaeoaaena -3 . we. oases 293 implications for the entire country. The implementation of the first phase created some Opposition from within the government as well as from outside of the government. By the end of the summer 1962, Opposition was beginning to organize. The largest owners, many of whom held high government positions, sought to erode the law by questioning the depth of Arsanjani's hasty implementation. On the other hand, Amini was seem as a man threatening the unity of the Shah's absolute power from within. First Prime Mininster Amini was forced to resign in July 1962. This incident did not have an instant effect on the land program since Arsanjani remained in his office in the new cabinet. The new prime minister, Asadullah Alam, was a prominent member of one of Iran‘s largest landowning families. From outside the government, the land reform carried on with some opposition from some landlords and clergy men. In fact the landowning class in general were strongly opposed to the reform on grounds of personal interest. Tribal opposition to land reform began to appear in late 1962. On November 12, 1962, Malek Abedi, chief of the Firuzabad Land Reform Organization in Fars Province, was assassinated (Tehran Journal, 1962) and the government put the region under Martial Law. "Between November, 1962, and the following March nearly one hundred soldiers and citizens were killed in the struggle over distribution in Fare" (Baldvin,1967:105). The backbone of the tribal resistance in Fars was broken in early June 1963 when Abduallah Khan Zarghampour, chief 294 of the Boyer Ahmad tribe was killed in the Siyah Mountains twelve miles from Dehdasht when he resisted while surrounded by Government forces. At the same time, some clergymen announced their opposi- tion to the land reform program. This opposition was simul- taneous with the progressive uprising of June 1963. I should mention here that most of the Western scholars expert on Iranian land reform believe that the main.issue of the June uprising was the land reform. It is clear today that the progressive clergy opposition was much deeper than an simple opposition to land distribution.3 The state won the first round against those landowners and clergyman who opposed the land reform. In this phase the- government used mostly army forces. On.the other hand, the Shah became convinced of the need for legislation to provide security of ownership to landlords, while abolishing the sharecropping relations. For this purpose, Arsanjani was no longer suitable for the program. His mission was finished here and in March 1963 he resigned at the request of the Shah. His resignation gave encouragement to those both in and out of government who desired a more leisurely rate of land reform . 12.4. The Laws and Regulations of the Phase Two In a situation of growing political opposition from landlords and religious leaders, the Shah's attitude toward the land reform changed, as illustrated by his choosing a military officer, General Ismail Riahi, to succed Arsanjani 295 as Minister of Agriculture. The Shah had no interest on the socio-economic conditions of the villages, and thus no commitment to develop the kind of agricultural program which would assure the long-term success of the peasants. This was demonstrated by new governmental policy during the second phase of the land reform. Riahi's appointment created a slow pace of redistribution and priorities had changed. The second phase of the land reform was formally embodied in a series of Cabinet decrees which became known as the "Annexed Articles" (Promulgated January 17,1963). In 1963 parliamentary elections were held and the version of the Annexed Articles were approved in July 1964 and became known as the Additional Article (Richards,1975:8). The aims of this phase were, on the one hand, to change the agricultural production system in a way that would abolish sharecropping practices, and on the other hand, to prevent the radical expansion of independent peasantry in favor of a new system of large landholding and agricultural practice. It would be relevent to quote professor Lambton (1969:215): ... those holding the reigns of power began to realize that the emergence of an independent peasantry might constitute a new factor in the-political situation and threaten their own power. In short, the aim was apparently to do away with the remnants of feudalism, but in fact it turned out to be a retreat from the land reform and hence beneficial to the large-holders. According to the second phase laws, all owners of the exempted villages from the first phase have a choice of five 296 ways of settlement: 1) Landlords could lease their villages to the peasants, i.e., those who were working on the cultivated and cultivable lands of the village. This lease was a cash rental on the basis of its weighted average revenue calculated from revenues obtained during the three previous years. The period of the lease was up to 30 years, and the rental would be revised every five years (Lambton,1969:194). 2 V Sale to the peasants: Land could be sold to the peasants on the basis of a mutual agreement about the price between peasants and landlord. Before the sale could be completed, land reform officials were required to certify that the prospective purchasers were actually nasaq holders, since the sale of plots to other than nasaq holders was prohibited. (Ibid.). 3) Division of Land: Irrigated and dry farming lands could be divided between the resident peasants and the landlord according to the customary division of the share-cropping, which as discussed earlier, was on the basis of the five factors of land, water, seed, labor and oxen. If this type of agreement was selected by the landlord, then he was held responsible for management and for using modern cultivation methods Ibid. . 4) Formation of a share-holding a ricultural unit (Jointestock agricultural unit .In this alternative landlord and peasants should work jointly as share- holders in a communal enterprise. Each member's number of shares in the unit would be in proportion to his share of the unit's assets, taking into consideration land, livestock and tools. Profits from the sale of crops would be distributed among memebers according to each's share. Supervision of each agricultural unit would be entrusted to a managing committee composed of one representative of the landowner (s), one representative of peasants, and a third person chosen by mutual agreement (Ibid, 204-206). Sale of peasants' cultivation rights: Land-owners whose cultivated land did not exceed a specified maximum cguld purchase the rights of nasaq holding peasants. 5 V During the second Phase further attention was paid to endowment lands. Villages which were vaqf-i amm (publicly endowned) should be rented to the local peasant on the 297 basis of 99 year leases. Villages which were vaqf-i khas (privately endowed) could be purchased by peasant or could be rented for 30 years (Denman, 1978:272-3). The nature of the laws of the second phase is consi- derable, since on the surface they seem beneficial to the peasant, but in reality they offered the landlord opportunities to choose their own ways of dealing with the peasants. Generally from the land-owners’ point of view the tenancy agreement was the continuation of the status quo, particularly when the leases were open to revision every five years. The landlords did not lose anything and gained a Government- enforced lease. From the perspective of peasants, the tenancy agreements brought some disadvantages. For them, the obligation to pay cash rents was the chief burden of tenancies. This obligation forced the peasants toward the market-and monetarization. Under the second option (sale to the peasant), the new peasant owners had to meet a price set by the landlords. Under this condition, they were robbed by the landlord. In alternative three (division of land) the peasants obtained a small plot of the lands, due to the nature of the division of crops. Option four (formation of a joint-stock agricultural unit) was a version of the old.landlord-peasant relationship with a different name. Since most of the landlords were resident in the cities and could not supervise the agricultural unit, they entrusted their agricultural affairs to the peasants which meant the continuation of the share-cropping 298 —i— system. The final option (sale of peasants' cultivation rights) legitimized absentee landownership and harmed the peasants since they gained nothing and lost their cultivation rights. Like phase one, phase two included some exemptions. The Land Reform Council ruled that cultivated lands, within the boundaries of urban areas were not eligible for land reform (Research Group,1970:59). Another exemption was the mechanized farms. An owner could exempt 500 hectares from the provision of the additional articles, as long as he used a tractor to plow it and hired wage laborers to cultivate it (Salmanzadeh,1980:65). But according to the fourth note of the Additional Article, the land-owner was percitted to develop his farm even above this size limit (Azkia,1980:53). In fact, there was no limitation on the amount of mechanized land that one owner could hold. Exemption of the mechanized land was a direct effort to expand the capitalist relations of production since it emphasized wage labor. 12.5. The Results of the Second Phase The Additional Articles of 17 January 1963, unlike the first phase of the land reform, were not put into operation immediately. The implementation began in February, 1965 when it was approved by the Majlis and put into effect immediately (Lambton,1969:194). Although the implementation of the second phase continued until 1972, it soon became clear that the first option (letting the land on a thirty year lease) was the favorite. About 80% of the second stage 299 *— transactions created tenancies. A total of 40,000 villages, (including some 12,000 partially settled under the first phase), and 21,912 farms were affected (Sazaman—i islahat—i arzi, 1966:3). There were 227,490 landlords who rented their land to 1,246,652 peasants (Ibid.). By implementing the second alternative (the sale of landlord's land to the peasants) 57,164 peasants bought land from 3,275 landlords (Ibid.). As we can see, there were few landlords who were demented enough to voluntarily sell their land and water to the government so that the latter could redistribute them to the peasants. This occurred only in cases where there was not really any genuine land or water and these were abstract names rather than anything else (GOPF,1976:42). About 156,279 peasants, received small plots of land as a consequence of 22,646 landlords deciding to divide up their lands according to option three (sazenam-i islahat-i arzi,1966:3). There are no data to indicate the average size of the farms which had been given to each peasant. One organization's statistics indicated that the amount of land received by each peasant was so small that it could not possibly support a family. Their calculation is that some of them acquired as little as 1/4 of a hectare of land (GOPF,1976:44-45). Based on establishment of the "joint-stock agricultural unit", a total of 83,267 peasants received shares (sazeman-i islahat-i arzi, 1966:3). Comparing the number of landlords 300 —:— (41,774) who set up the joint units with the number of peasants (83,267) show that two peasants, on average, shared the land with each landlord. This indicates that this option was favored by the small absentee landholders. As I mentioned before, this option was in fact share-cropping under another name, since the absentee landowners were notinvolved in practicing agriculture. Under option five, a small number of families, (17,157 of them) 'sold' their land to the landlords (Ibid.). Over half of these were in an area controlled by the powerful Alam family (Halliday, 1979:117). It seems likely that peasants who submitted to this alternative were mostly forced to do so. Under the option of a ninety-nine year tenancy agreement between the zaqf_administrators and nasaq-holding peasants, another 172,103 peasants established tenancy contracts with the vaqf administration (sazeman-i islahat-i arzi,1966:3). The annual rent, at least during the initial five years, was lower than value of shares of the harvest they owned prior to the reform (Hooglund,1982:80). It is believed that some, vaqf lands were sold to the peasants in a few cases where the administrators of the vaqf felt it would be more beneficial to sell the land and invest the money in other activities (Ibid.,165). In total 213,443 peasant share-croppers acquired land under phase two of the land reform, as compared to 432,043 who had received it under phase one of land reform. The statistics for redistribution under the second phase are 301 summarized in Table 12.2. These figures clearly show that the aim of the second phase of the land reform was to halt the distribution of land. Table 12.2: Land‘Reform Options Under Phase Two Owners Villages Affected in Choosing Peasants Option . Whole or in Part Option Affeczcd 99-year vaqf leases 12,052 ' 16,278 172,103 30-year tenancies 40,000 test.) - 227,490 1,246,652 Owner sale of land ‘ 3,275 57,164 Owner-peasant division of ‘ 22,646 156,279 land ' ' Owner-peasant joint stock 3,977 ' - 41,774 83,267 corporations Owner purchase of 15,024 . 8,9§9 17,157 cultivation rights a) Figures are not ayailable. . (Source: Sazaman-i islahat-1 ar21,.1966. Generally, peasants were not satisfied with the result of the second phase because they did not receive ownership of the land except in a minority of cases, and the terms under which they received it were less favorable to them than under the first phase. Thus, there was naturally widespread peasant disappointment with the result of the second phase. Peasants commonly expressed the view that the options were not explained to them adequately. Therefore, peasants felt that tenancy agreements had been illegally forced upon them by their landlords. According to an investigation done by Ajami, the peasant were made to sign a piece of paper which later turned out to be related to one of the options more beneficial to landlords than to peasants (Ajami,1970). In 302 short, the peasants got the impression that these objection- able "choices" were being forced upon them by deceptive and insensitive officials. The second phase not only did not satisfy those peasants who anticipated the opportunity to acquire land, it also generated more anger among tenant peasants. The hostility toward landlords, and violence against their property became common in various districts. The peasants protested to the land reform offices, saying that they did not know the nature of the papers they had signed, but the officials paid no attention to their complaints and took the side of the land- lords. In fact, the state won the second round against the peasant movement that was coming into being by either ignoring the complaining peasants, or arresting "agitator" peasants. 12.6. The Law and Supplementary Measures of the Phase Three. This phase coincided with the government's policy of modernization of farming. It contained three stages: the creation of farm corporations; the amendment providing for the sale of tenancies; and the encouragement of agri-businesses. In fact this stage was set up to eradicate the remnants of the feudal system of production. In 1965, the Shah told the High Economic Council that measures had to be devised to consolidate uneconomic forming units,eXpand the area under irrigation, and increase agricultural productivity. In the short run these goals could only be acheived, the Shah asserted, through the creation of what he called "farm corporations".5 Official visits were 303 made to Israel to study the Kibbutzim and the moshav. A year later, the Shah again urged the formation of such economically viable units, called for mechanization, and state a preference to see the villages administered as farm Corporations (Denman,1973:210). The first stage of phase three (December,1965) outlined a law setting forth the guidelines for the establishment of farm corporations which were, in nature, an elaborate reformu- lation of the concept of "joint-stock farm units" of the Additional Articles (Katouzian,1974:228). On March 20, 1968, the constitution of these companies was approved (Earham, 1977:112). Theoretically, the principal objective of this law was to speed up the "modernization" of agriculture through the introduction of high rates of capital investment, mechanized production, and the specialized cultivation of cash crops, all of which was to be achieved by concentrating fragmented individual holdings into vast corporate tracts. The law relative to the creation of the farm corporation indicated that "... it is hoped that the holding of each share-holder will be no less than 50 acres of irrigated, or 100 acres of nonpirrigated land" (Brun,1978:18). Farm corporations were established in 1968 for a five- year trial period. In practice, the establishment of farm corporations, which would turn independent peasant property into paper shares of the large corporations, led to the concentration of ownership (through the sale of paper shares 304 by smallholders to big proprietors, thus creating absentee capitalist farmers as well as peasant wage laborers) and resulting in the state management of farm corporations by officials sent from Tehran or the provincial capital. Yet, the most damaging effect of this policy was to destroy the historic boundaries of the Iranian village as an autonomous unit of social life and labor. In short, this stage was concerned with the consolidation of small units into big ones. The growing dissatisfaction with the results of the second phase tenancy "reform" began to be divulged to Tehran at a time when the government was involved in formulating various agricultural deve10pment policies. Consequently, the government began considering another action toward land redistribution. On the other hand, the official policy formu- lators believed that one obstacle to mechanization was the fact that a majority of peasants were tenants, while their lands ‘were owned largely by urbanites. They conclude that if the tenants were to become owners, then this change in status would provide a base for the establishment of farm corporation and consequently the "mechanization" of agricultural methods (Hooglund,1982:69). Therefore, the second stage was designed to rectify the anomalies of the leasehold tenancies. On July 13,1969, the law provided that in the following cases: (1) Lands rented according to option one of phase two, whether or not the lease contract had been drown up; 305 (ll) Lands included in "join-stock agricultural units"; (111) All lands which had remained in the hands of the landlord after the first and second phases; should be dealt with in either of the following ways: (1) Sale to the peasant,or (2) Division according to the ownership of agricultural factors and apportioning the shares of landlord and peasant (Earham,1971:106). In fact, the five settlement options of phase two were reduced to two. The law did not apply to the land in villages constituting I§q£_property (leased for ninety nine years), nor did it affect any of the exemptions in force for mechanized land. Finally, I should mention that the purchase price would be equivalent to twelve years' rent, with payment arrangements worked out by mutual agreement between owner and tenant (Denman,1973). In this stage government did not intervene in price setting. The change of policy in favor of concentration and 'modernization' took yet another turn with the strategy of establishing large agri-business complexes. This policy was intended to create large-scale capitaistic farms, in the style of the Latin American latifundia, in the areas where the fertility of the soil and availability of water supplies (officially described as 'the poles of land and water resources') made it most attractive for land-extensive farming. As H.Richards has mentioned, the fundations for the Shah's foray into large-scale agri-business were laid during the second Seven Year Plan (1955-62) when the head of the 306 ’ Plan Organization, Ebtehaj, at a World Bank meeting in Istanbul in September 1955 invited David E. Lilienthal, former Chairman of the Tennessee Vally Authority (TVA) and (the Atomic Energy Commission, to visit Iran in order to examine the possibilities for a unified regional development scheme similar to TVA (1975:12). The 1968 law on "The Establishment of Compaines for Utilization of Lands Downstream of Dams" says that the government has a right to purchase necessary lands from landlords and landowning peasants in order to release it to agribusinesses created by state and/ or private domestic or foreign investment (Salmanzadeh,1980:3). According to the Agri-business Law the size of these farms should not be less than 5,000 hectares (Azkia,1980:125). This last stage of the Third phase was a direct attempt to dispossess peasants in hundreds of villages in the most fertile areas of the country, and use them as wage laborers to work on corporate land. This policy was, put in Katouzian's words, "a despotic pseudo-modernist strategy which deformed Iranian agriculture" (1981:302). 12.7. The Outcomes of the Phase Three Implementation of the 1969 Law took nearly two and a half years, and was officially completed in 1972. Land Reform Organization statistics indicate some 758,119 peasants had purchased their tenancies by the end of 1972; in addition, 61,805 others acquired land as a result of owners choosing to divide their land with peasants (Sazamanri islahat-i arzi, 307 —7— The faithful performance of the distribution law of 1969 would have resulted in virtually all peasants gaining the land they cultivated. However, in this phase, the government played little role. As a result landlords sold their land at their own convenience and at a higher price than that which was legally permitted. In the option of the division of land between landlords and tenants, many influential landlords kept the better quality land and gave poor land for redis- tribution. ‘ In relation to implementation of the law of establishment of the farm corporation, the first corporation established in Shiraz was near Persepolis in 1968. By the end of December 1977,93 Farm corporations had been established in different regions of Iran (Azkia,1980:153). It was estimated that by the end of the 1979, the number would reach 140. In fact this did not happen, as a result of the failure of the program. Finally, as a result of the Law of Agri-business, there were about 15 large agri-businesses throughout the country up to 1978, whose plantations ranged in size from 5,000 to 25,000 hectares. Eleven out of this total were established in Khuzistan; their total extent came to 67,000 hectares (Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Affairs,1976). Also, there were 22 agri-business enterprises ranging in size from 1,000 to 5,000 hectares, which were mostly owned by Iranian businessmen (Dumont,1976:25). The success or failure of the farm corporations and agri-businesses means the prosperity or unfulfillment of the state in a fight against the independent peasantsfor 308 —i— modernizing agriculture. This is part of my concern in part V of this dissertation. 12.8. A Summary of 1962-1971 Land Redistribution As the land reform moved from its first phase, it became less and less effective as an instrument of land redistribution. If the laws of the first stage had been put into effect carefully, without any trickey by the.landlords with the connivance of Government agents, the number of villages given to the peasants (and consequently the number of peasants families owning their lands), would have been far greater. Since the size of nasaq varied significantly among the peasants within a single village, and also among the peasants of different villages, the outcome of land reform was uneven. By using the existing pre-capitalist structure of the villages as the basis for their policy, one could conclude that the officials deliberately designed the laws to distribute land unequally, to benefit the richer farmers and to exclude at least half of the rural population from its scope. The more important point is the insufficiency of the distributed land. According to an authoritative source the amount of land the peasants received in many cases did not make up a viable holding. The cultivated land held by nearly 40% of peasants did not exceed more than 2 hectares per family (Khosrovi,1979:81), while the threshold of viability outside the north part of Iran is 10 hectares per family. 509 The result of ten years of land reform are impressive. In early 1962 before any redistribution had taken place there were 3.2 million rural households, of which 2.4 million had cultivation rights or were independent peasants (Bank Markazi Iran,1972). As a result of the phase one and two reforms, about 966,701 peasant households had received or bought land. The law of phase three added about 799,924 peasant households to this group. In total 1,766,625 households benefitted from the land reform (see table 12.3). This figure of 1.7 million households was 53% of the total number of rural households, and 70% of the peasant share-croppers in the country. ‘ Table 12.3: Land Redistribution Summary ' Tatal peasants with haqqei nasaq, 1962 2,100,028 Peasants acquiring land Under Phase 1 753,258 Under Phase 2 Owner sale to peasants 57,164 Owner division with peasants 156,279 Under Phase 3 Purchase of 30-year tenandies 738,119 Owner division with peasants 61,805 Tatal 1,766,625 Peasants holding 99-year vaqf leases 172,103 Toral beneficiaries of land rediStribution 1,938,728 Peasants not obtaining land 161,300 Percentage of nasaq holders obtaining land 92% Sources: Sazaman-i islahat-i arzi, 1961-72. Generally speaking, the government actually sought to protect the interest of the small and medium-scale absentee owners (through phases 2 and 3). As a consequence, tens of thousands of absentee owners still remained after 1972, although the great and powerful landlords had virtually disappeared. 510 12.9.Endnotes 1. For the purpose of implementation of the law, a household 4. 5. was regarded as one person. This definition was confirmed by the thirty-sixth session of the Land Reform Council. But the forty-third session of the L.R.C. (7/6/1963) reversed this definition by declaring that women land- owners in the same way as men, and irrespective of their position in the household, are entitled to the upper legal limit of land. Further, on 8/25/63, the forty- seventh session of the L.R.C. issued a decree which also entitled dependent children of the landlords to the upper legal limit (Lambton, 1960:55). This should not be generalized to all the land reform officials. In fact the land reform organization was among only a few governmental institutions whose staffs were dedicated. The June 1963 uprising under the leadership of Ayatollah Khomini denounced the regime for living off corruption, rigging elections, viola ing the constitutional laws, stifling the press and political parties, destroying the independence of the university, neglecting the economic needs of merchants, workers and peasants, underming the country's Islamic beliefs, encouraging Westernization, granting capitulations to foreigners, selling oil to Israel, and constantly expanding the size of the central bureaucracies. The maximum acount of land any owner could hold and still be permitted to buy the cultivation rights of peasants varied from 30 to 200 hectares depending on the location and productivity of land (Homayon, 1963:18). It is interesting enough to see that he did not asked the "experts" to find a solution to the agricultural problem. Instead, he claimed that farm corporations were the solution. 311 PART V RURAL SOCIETY AFTER THE LAND REFORM INTRODUCTION: Emergence of the New Rural Socio-economic Structure The implementation of the land reform was a turning point in the development of contemporary Iranian rural areas. The land reform and its accompanying measures swiftly changed the socio-economic conditions in rural areas, enhanced the development of differentiated agri- cultural enterprises and property systems, and thereby modified the class structure of Iranian rural communities. Characterized as a "reform from above," the land reform program eradicated the pre-capitalist relations of production, and superimposed new relations of production. As a result of the land reform, the precapitalist estate was transformed either into a transitory system of production, or into a capitalist one, thus changing the bais of the social relations of production. The former category includes the independent peasant production and the agricultural unit based mainly on tenant farming. The latter category includes capitalist peasants, commer- cial farmers, farm-corporations and agri-businesses. Even though the transition to capitalism in rural Iran is only a recent phendmenon and is by no means fully 312 completed, the social relations in agriculture are essenp tially nonfeudal: land and labor are increasingly commo- dified and their appropriation is more and more estab- lished on a competitive basis. The majority of the product is the result of either capitalist or petty commodity production. The only difference between a capitalist producer and a petty commodity producer is the capacity to generate and expropriate a surplus via the use of hired labor. As we know, the transition to capitalism is not an instantaneous process but a gradual one, over decades at least, and one accompained by lags, apparent resistances and a diversity of forms. In the case of Iran the land reform program attempted to cultivate capitalist relations of production in the countryside and had considerable success in destroying the pre-capitalist system of social relations. However, it could be argued that the reinfor- cement of the independent peasant and tenancy sector constitutes a brake of the full development of capitalist relations of production in the countryside. It is the intention of this part to explore the emergence and structure of the new rural enterprises in order to be able to draw a comprehensive picture of the new rural class relations. By this, then, we can see the effect of the land reform on Iranian rural class structure. 313 CHAPTER THIRTEEN FORTIEICATION 0F TRANSITIONAL SYSTEMS 0E PRODUCTION 13.1. Introduction The first intention of the present chapter is to demonstrate that the elimination of the share-cropping system (both muzara-eh and muqata-eh) did not result automatically in the establishment of capitalist relations of production in the countryside. Except for areas that the government attempted to establish capitalist relations of production, the predominant systems of production which emerged after the reform were transitory systems of production..This chapter will explain how muqasa-meh was sharply expanded; and how the new tenancy farming (tulmbeh EEEE) started to emerge as a transitory system of production. The second aim in this chapter is to show how the major pre-capitalist collective organization of production (bgngh) was transformed and gradually dissolved by the reform. Although it was believed by land reform officials that rural cooperative societies could replace the bgngh system and would fill up the gap which would result from the destruction of the bunghs, in reality no village-level institution ever has replaced their functions. Finally, I will elucidate that one of the main results 314 of land reform was the emergence of the independent peasant system of production. This new transitory system of production was very beneficial to the capitalist system of production since it was a good source of cheap labor to produce cheap food. On the other hand, it was easy to consoldiate the lands belonging to the independent peasants in order to establish large-scale farming in the areas which were suitable for capitalist activities. In relation to the independent producer, I will also explore the situation of non-farm petty commodity production, as it is effected by land reform and its supplementary measures. 13.2. Elimination of share-cropping (muzara-eh and muqata-eh) With redistribution of the land among the nasaq-holders . and creation of the independent peasants; with exemption of some of the lands from redistribution (i.e., mechanized land); with the provision of establishment of tenancy farming; and finally with the selling of the peasant cultivation right (nasaq) to the landlord, the muzara-eh and muqata-eh social relations have disappeared rapidly. After a decade of implementing the land reform, share-cropping characterizes perhaps only a small fraction of the total number of farms. Some experts on Iranian rural change believe that even before the land reform, muzara-eh disappeared in some parts of the country as a result of the mechanization of agri- culture (Khosrovi, 1976:78). As I have explained before (chapter seven), the expansion of real mechanized farming 515 through the country before the land reform was limited to the Gorgan region. Under particular circumstances, this mechani- zation was established on the non-cultivating lands of the region. Although this action stimulated the expansion of mechanized land among some cultivating lands of the region, it did not replace muzara-eh with other systems in the majority of the feudal lands. In other parts of the country, muzara-eh and muqata-eh remained intact until the land reform. There is no doubt that, as a result of the Iranian land reform, the forms of generating products and the mode of surplus extraction were to a great, if still incomplete, extent changed. Although land reform in Iran did not eliminate large landownership in the rural areas, the new concentration of land was not for the purpose of continuation of share— cropping. Neither new landowners nor formerhnafaqfholders were willing to continue with the share-cropping system. From the new landowners' point of view, it was more profite- able to pay wages to the peasants or to lease out his farm to tenants for cash. In contrast to the landowners, the peasants preferred to have their own plot and not to work for a share of the crops. To my knowledge, the incidence of muzare-eh and muqata-eh relations of production was not very widespread at the end of the land reform period. 316 15.3. Prevalence_of Tenancy Farming (nimeh kari and tulumbeh E5211 "' As I demonstrated in chapter seven, a particular type of tenancy farming (muqasa-meh) existed prior to the land reform. This system was modified and increased as an.unexpected result of the land reform. It has been called nimeh kari mostly after the land reform. Alongside nimeh kari, there is another form of tenancy farming known as tulumbeh kari. This transi- tory system of land exploitation was created after the land reform. Nimeh kari has prevailed since the land reform in Iran. This system emerged as a result of different actions. In some cases, the land had been bought by a few rich peasants from small peasants and then had been rented to the tenant farmers (Ashraf, 1975:30). In other cases, the landlord had bought the cultivation right (nassaq) of share-croppers and converted the land to cash crops, with the help of tenant farmers (Azkia, 1980:114). Finally, in many cases, the landlords who exempted the most productive land from redis— tribution turned their land to nimeh kari (Ajami, 1970:69). One of the main characteristics of this system of production is that the tenancy agreement between the landowner and the tenant is based on a short-term contract, which remains in force for one or two years. The tenancy agreement is mainly for cultivation of vegetables and sayfi (Azkia, 1980:112). The second characteristic of the system is that the tenant farmers have extensive knowledge and experience in 317 agricultural affairs, especially about sayfi crOps. The tenant farmers are usually well-to-do peasants and some of them originally came from the central parts of the country. They move around the country looking for land to rent at bargain prices (Ibid., P.113). The third characteristic is that these peasants live on rented farms for the period of cultivation and are not involved in social activities of the village. They are considered by the residents of the villages as a marginal group. They cultivate the land with the help of the agri— cultural laborers who are brought from the tenant farmers' villages as migratory laborers (Research Group, 1969:286). The fourth peculiarity of the nimeh kari system is its management. The management of the enterprise is based on the decision making of the tenant himself. Whatever is the decision of the tenant, the owners of the land expebt a fixed rent from him regardless of success or failure of the crOps (Ashraf, 1975:59). The fifth distinction of the nimeh kari is that in tenancy agreements the provision of land, water and half of the fertilizer cost are the owner's duty, while providing the other factors of production such as labor, seed, agri- cultural implements and the remaining half of the fertilizer is the tenant's responsibility (Azkia, 1980:115). The sixth characteristic is that the tenant farmers make another contract (in addition to the contract with 318 landowners) with various middlemen in the town markets in order to sell their products (Ashraf, 1975:59). Nimeh kari has been established mostly for producing summer crops for market. They are usually located close to the big cities and towns. Their production is labor intensive. One of the reasons that nimeh kari has been expanded after the land reform is its labor intensive character. They are beneficial to capitalism since they produce labor intensive croPs.For example, in a village near Marvdasht in.Fars province, the capitalist owner of 500 hectares of land of the village leased out 30 hectares to an outsider tenant farmer to cultivate labor intensive crops (i.e., watermelon and so on), while he cultivated sugar- beets on rest of his land using mechanized equipment and wage laborers (Ajami, 1970). The value of the products sold by the nimeh karan is high. In the above mentioned village, for 30 hectares cultivation in 1966-67, 1,650,000 rials products were sold. For that year, the pure income of each nimeh kar was 43,000 rials for seven.months work which in contrast to the income of the independent peasant producers of that region was really high (Ibid., pp. 61-62). The development of the nimeh kari increases unemployment in many villages of the country since nimeh karan bring their own.laborers from outside the villages to work. This is one of the reasons that nimeh karan are not welcome among the residents of the villages. 319 Nimeh kari has a contradictory characteristic. On the one hand, they are exploited in relation to both landowners and middlemen and contractors of the market. On the other hand, since they work with the help of agricultural laborers, they exploit these laborers to some extent. Their positions are quite risky since they are dependent on Lmarket price fluctuations. It has been reported that some of them became bankrupt. However, their situations in general are better than independent peasants and they survive the development of capitalism because of their ability to deliver food to consumers at a lower price than the capitalist. As I mentioned before, there is another form of tenancy farming known as tulumbeh kari. This has a minor difference with nimeh kari in terms of land—ownership. One of the main reasons for the emergence of the tulumbeh kari after the land reform was the problem of providing water for irrigation. Tulumbeh karan rented the unirrigated land and by investing in digging semi-deep wells, they have provided an adequate water supply. This usually happens on the marginal lands of the villages. Another reason for the emergence of tulumbeh kari is insufficiency of the lands of poor peasants after the land reform and a lack of credit’to invest in production. Therefore, the poor peasant prefares to lease out his land to tulumbeh kar and seeks job on others“ land or in towns. In this system of production, a specialized peasant has taken the risk of investment in farming activities. He provides water, seeds, water pump, and all other cultivation implements. The labor power comes either from family labor 320 or hiring some agricultural laborers. The agricultural laborer in the case of tulumbeh kari, unlike nimeh kari, comes from the village itself (Ashraf, 1975:69). In tulumbeh kari the owner of the land does not intervene in decision-making . The head of the family is the major manager of the enterprise. As Ajami has indicated, these enterprises are more inclined to increase their yield and introudce new methods for cultivation. Therefore, in order to increase output per hectare they have cultivated the land according to capitalist farmers' norms. Intensive farming is often found in their agricultural units. They have set aside less land as fallow, by providing more water to cultivate a larger proportion of their land. Their crops are usually labor intensive and for their seasonal work they hire wage laborers. Most of these enterprises are run by specialized, experienced, peasants. Because of their profitability, cash and summer crops (sayfi) are the main'products of these enterprises. These agri- cultural units are mostly concentrated around the cities (Ajami. 1970). The ability of tulumbeh karan for investment in agri- cultural machinery is not high, but in contrast, they have a high ability to invest in digging the wells and installing water pumps. In one village, for example, on average each tulumbeh kar family invested 138,140 rials for supplying the;water (Ashraf, 1975:76). This amount is very high by comparison to the investments of the nimeh kari and independent peasant families. 321 Each tulumbeh kar family invested an average 179,639 rial in all agricultural necessities during 1966-67. He sold 335,743 rials products. Therefore on average, he earned 122,532 rials from selling his agricultural products. Tulumbeh kar family usually has some livestock. It has been estimated that he can earn 10,000 rials from selling livee stock products. Consequently, the average net income of a tulumbeh kar family in the year investigated was 132,532 rials (Ashraf, 1975:78). Comparing this with the pure income of the nimeh kar in the same year shows that tulumbeh kar income was three times higher than nimeh kar's. This is because the yield per hectares in tulumbeh kar units was higher than that of nimeh kar and even independent peasants (or. Ajami, 1970). '.According to some stuides there is evidence that the tulumbeh karan, after renting the land :from the small peasants for a few years, have bought the land andsexpanded their farms (Azkia, 1980:116). At the same time, it has been reported that these agricultural units have been threatened by the uninstitutionalized arrangements for supplying credits (Rural Research Group, 1968: 50). Tulumbeh karan have obtained credit for investment in water supply from various middlemen and urban merchants. Borrowing the credit allowed the merchants to monopolize the buying and selling of all products belonging to the tulumbeh kar. As a result, the contractors usually buy the crops at a lower price than the free market price. In addition, the merchants intervene 322 in the decision-making regarding the type of crops that should be cultivated for each year (Ashraf, 1975:69-71). Therefore, the degree of involvement of the merchants in decision-making effects the amount of yield and the hectares under cultivation. A comprehensive survey of these agricultural units has not been carried out yet. One thing is clear about this system of production; it is spreading rapidly. At the beginning, it was found mostly in Fars and Bandar Abbas provinces. Gradually it is becoming widespread in the country. As I mentioned above, there is a tendency for its expansion and rapid transformation to either independent peasant production or to the capitalist activities. But at the same time there is a threat against it in relation to market and middlemen. 13.4. Transformation and Gradual Disappearance of the buneh system_ Iranian villages experienced significant socio—economic changes after the land reform. These changes transformed the organization of labor which had prevailed in village society. The practical effect of redistribution was the break-down of traditional units of agricutural production in some regions, in which all agricultural activities were under- taken collectively. Unfortunately, the governmental officials who drafted the land reform law totally ignored the structure and function of buneh. The land was distributed to the 323 individual nasaq—holders instead of buneh. The first effect was the division of the bppeh organization. The practical effects of the destruction of the tradi- tional pppeh system were many. First, as we know, the bppgh organization gave socio-economic security to its members. Although the leading members had some social and economic privilege over other members, even the weakest members were sheltered against socio-economic difficulties. After the disintegration of the bungh system, the lower members, who were accustomed to working within the frame- work of a bungh, could not COpe with the socio-economic pressures. Secondly, the destruction of ppp§h_caused a rapid process of social and economic polarization and strati- fication within the village population. The disintegration opened the way for stronger elements among the peasantry to concentrate more and more social and economic power in their hands at the expense of others. Since working together was a necessity to the Iranian peasantry, redistribution of land among individual members of the bupgh meant that some peasants could not do all the specialized work such as irrigation which needed more experience and cooperation.1 As a result, after the land reform there existed a strong tendency among the peasants to keep the ppneh intact for some years, especially in regions which faced a scarcity of water (Saedloo,1978:80). However, there were changes in the terms under which bunehs operated; most importantly, the privileges, which had 324 resulted in an inequitable distribution of both labor and the harvest,were eliminated (Safinezhad, 1974:178). There is evidence which indicates that in certain villages bunehs have survived quite well, albeit in greatly modified form (Ibid.). In spite of the peasants' ambitions and attempts to preserve the traditional system of production, in the course of time these bunehs could not meet the challenge of the newly created socio-economic conditions and began to break up. In additionato this, since lands were redis- tributed unequally, those who received large amounts of land thought cooperation with smaller holders was less practical than hiring agricultural laborers (Hooglund,1981: 174). Therefore, economic considerations have reinforced a trend toward 92232 dissolution. Table 13.1 represents the course of disintegration of the 92229 structure in the village of Table- Abad in the period after the land reform. In this village, the peasants who received land were organized in 15 four-household bunehs. After nine years, all _of them had broken up except for a few with very strong family ties (Safinezhad, 1974). The 15 production teams in the year 1965-66 have increased to 47 production units in the year 1973-74. It is clear that in spite of the peasants’ attempts, the continuation of the 92225 system of multi-household production teams have proved impossible because of the new conditions. Similar fragmentation and atomizing processes were reported from many villages in different parts of the country. 325 .esma .esssneaasm ”sea om 3 co co '32:.5: A ~ .~ “a . a a. o u a: a... II I: II II IIIIIIIITIIII m. ..... I .I ..I II INEIIIIIIIIII : 0... DUI _ QIOII QIOII OIOI’O .IOII ,IOIOIO 0+: Mu coo. .1 cool. cool. of. IilllloIIJIIoar 7.01: “Hm—H 0.10.910 0.0... 0.10 .0... II II II OIOII 2 o 0.10:6 0 0+6 T010 7010 01010 9101010 010101. c— .0010 .0016 .0010 II It... I‘vlfilifi a 9.9.. II I: II II I: II infill-I4! II .... OIOII 7910... olOlOlo 9101016 9101610 , n .0 cool. 0.916 001‘ 0.0!. II IIJolOIOIo 0101016 1.11110 0. on .00. .0 cool. I our .0910 If m. o I 9;. .9101. 0... III TIIoqulllfll c.1110... II II II II. III III 010.616 111» I I a... III. Ila olol" 0101: .u I II II II II II II II 91010:. a ll ............................................................. assaaaoz Showom pcm: map seems nasaaa> esn<-hnasa ea easaeaaam sheen mo coaasameaeamaa no mmaeoaa one ”a.ma manna 326 Bunehs' gradual but steady dissolution during the 1970s has produced a similar pattern in many villages. First, in a typical redistributed village, bunehs were re-established in the same number and size as existed before the reform. After a few years they expanded numberically by reducing their size. Finally, as peasants decided to cultivate their own land individually, the number of bunehs start decreasing over time. While bunehs have not disappeared completely from rural Iran, overall their decline has been dramatic.By 1977 the bunehs, as a village institution, had larely disappeared and those which remained were completely transformed in comparison to their roles before the reform. They no longer serve the central roles in the villages and no village-level institution has replaced their functions. As a result, this transformation and dissolution had an effect on both resources and agricultural production (Cf. Azkia, 1980). 13.5. Creation and Expansion of Rural Cooperative Societies The rural cooperative societies were created as a part of the land reform program, but they started to operate before the 1962 land reform implementation. By 1960 there were 636 cooperative societies with some 290,000 members (Ajami,1976:200). These societies rapidly eXpanded after 1962 since a share-cropper was required to belong to a rural cooperative if he was to obtain land. At this point these societies were transformed into fully governmental organizations. 327 They touched the lives of more rural families than any other organization. It was believed by land reform Officials that rural cooperatives could take over the duties of landlords and bunehs. Theoretically, the functions of cooperative societies were as follows: a) operations concerned with the production, exchange,storage, transport, and sale of the produce of members; b) provision of agricultural implements and machinery, fertilizers and pesticide; c) provision of consumption goods; d)extension of loans to members to tide them over the .period until they sell their crops; to provide what they need for cultivation of their crops, and where necessary provide money for improving the means of production (Lambton, 1969:293). Rural cooperatives were initiated, designed,created, super-impesed and stage—managed by a central bureaucratic network. No efforts were initiated to make the cooperative societies into genuine peasant partnerships. Rather, they became agencies for exercising bureaucratic control of rural affairs (Katouzian, 1974:233). The cooperative society consisted of independent peasants. The daily administration was in the hands of the board of directors (three members and two reserve members) who were appointed by the general assembly of all society members. They were elected for a two-year priod. The individual cooperatives elected delegates to the union. From each union a president and managing director were elected, but in practice 80 per cent of the 328 managing directors were government officials (Ashraf,1977:34). All unions were grouped together in the Central Organization for Rural Cooperatives (CORC) with headquarters in Tehran. Although many functions were mentioned for the rural cooperatives, very soon the explicit functions of the societies became distribution of credit and necessary consumer goods. In order to understand the distribution of credit to rural cooperative members, it is necessary to see the operation of the sponsoring financial agency. The financing procedure had three steps. First, at the regional level the Agricultural cooperative Bank allocated a sum negotiated annually to the Regional Union of Rural Cooperatives.2 Second, the Regional Union distributed this sum among the COOperatives. Finally, the cooperatives in turn distributed it to those members who requested loans (Ashraf,1977:38). By 1961, 960 cooperatives with 351,973 members granted 449 millions of rials loans. At the end of 1975 the number of cooperatives increased to 2,858 with 2,685,000 members and 24,723 millions of rials loans granted. The expansion of the cooperatives between 1961 and 1975 has been summarized in table 13.2. The loans genrally did not exceed 21,000 rials ($300) per year and were often well below this sum (the 1961 average was $40 per). In 1975 the average loan granted to a peasant household was $220 (this was the highest from 1961 to 1975) which was uncomparable to the norms proposed by the International Labor Organization ($1000 per agricultural 329 eon o~a_ .eaau-_: rho nc-vsn 1:: =-_. nouuaau n-.~ an» . 915$ 001nm..— Gav.- as can; :03: ewa.<3 93.» now 11.... nun-on . ho ‘22: no 2...: '3.“ 7—1.: vac: .... .53 Assn—a .nu_ Anvnaa to: 9-. .h .o .:o___.- silo: :23 0.3.;- s-E-uu 3-3 a: t. «a 383:! ...aa u 5.0.3» ...-Aunt eon noiuuuloau 3:: .9:— anon— uo>qasavaoou :2‘ we ESES—um ..~.= .... 330 household (Center for National Spatial Planning,1976:30). Even this amount was not available for all the peasants requesting loans in all villages. Over 15,000 villages were still without cooperatives in 1975 (Richard .1975z10). As I mentioned before, one of the functions of the cooperatives was provision of water supply. The cooperative societies that were charged with the responsibility of supervising and maintaining the traditional qanat_irrigation system of underground water channels did not fulfill their obligations, and the gang: system was allowed to decay (Ghorayshi, 1981:29). In relation to technical assistance, the cooperative members demanded help in the methods of using chemical fertilizers, improved seeds, irrigation, pest control, and agricultural machinery. Those in charge of the cooperatives were unable to adequately assist the peasants. An examination of technical guidance distributed within 142 cooperatives illustrates this problem: only 38 of these societies received help regarding chemical fertilizers, 36 had assistance in using improved seeds, 10 had help with irrigation, 22 were assisted with pest control, 26 in the use of agricultural machinery and only one had assistance in the use of loans (Institute for Social Studies and Research, 1970:133). The technological assistance was introduced only to men, while there was 7 per cent female members. For Iranian rural women, who were active participants in agricultural activities,especially in areas where rice was cultivated, 331 the introduction of technical assistance only to men had several implications. First it changed the status of women in relation to production. Secondly, in the course of agricultural development (if there was any), men's labor productivity tended to increase while women's remained more or less static. In the distribution of consumer goods, the cooperatives played an important role even though, at face value, they represented only a small part of the total consumption of the rural population (this was about 2 per cent excluding consumption of self produced goods) (center for National Spatial Planning, 1977:24). In fact, these cooperatives with their 4,4OO sales outlets and 2,685,000 memebers, created a densely patterned commercial network across the country (Ibid.). However, the expanSion of their activities on consumption needs could not effectively carry out one of their major roles (namely to cut the activites of the private sector). Only in the supply of tea and sugar did the amount obtained from cooperatives come close to the amount obtained on the free market (see Table 13.3). In short, the stress was put on co—operative buying, rather than co-operative farming. It was clear at the end of the 1970s that cooperatives failed to mobilize peasant resources for better farming. This helped to increase the role of the rural bourgeoisie and merchants from the cities in providing necessary loans for the peasants' survival. A 1968 survey of credit sources for relatively prosperous peasant families in several 332 Table 13.3: Areas where cooperative members obtain consumption needs Items where items are obtained Cooperatives free market Sugar and tea 47% 53% Clothes 3% 97% Household items 14% 86% Seeds,Fertilizers and other farming needs 36% 64% Others 16% 86% Sources: Plan and Budget Organization, 1973. districts showed that moneylenders still accounted for 38. % to 58.5% of the loans received (Denman,1973: 20-21). The interest rate of the loans from uninstitutionalized sources was very high. In relation to this issue, the cooperatives not only did not take the place of the exploitive rural middlemen, but it paved the way for the expansion of their activities by lacking sufficient credit to offer to the peasants. A survey in seven areas of Iran showed that some managers of the cooperatives had accepted "commissions” from members and in return gave them more credits (Rural Research Group, 1970). Different reports indicate that credit through the cooperatives was primarily advanced to well-to-do peasants since they were able to have influence over the cooperatives (Khamsi, 1969; Ashraf,1977; Azkia,1980; and Hooglund,1982). In short, cooperatives were another branch of the state bureaucracy rather than self-governing peasant societies. 333 They were under the control of the upper stratum of the peasantry. Their ability to provide credit to the poor peasant was low. One of their main functions was encouraging consumption of the town-made goods. They did not encourage cooperative farming and assistance at all. While the land reform has effectively destroyed the pppgh as a cooperative unit of production, the expansion of the cooperative societies was by no means a substitute for bunehs. 13.6. Expansion of Independent Peasant Production As I demonstrated before, one of the major effects of the land reform was to eliminate share-cropping and increase the number of peasant proprietors, and thus the size of the latter class increased to one-second of the rural population., After the land reform, independent peasant production became the most prevalent system of agricultural production in Iranian communities. It was found that until recently 40% of both irrigated and unirrigated land sown in cereals, 85% in rice and 46% in cotton was reported to be exploited by independent peasant family farms. And this group of peasants produced between 40%-50% of gross agricultural value added in 1972 (Statistical Center of Iran, 1974). As we can see from the above statistics the role of the independent peasant farm is very important in the overall agriculture of Iran. Independent peasants, consisting of former peasant proprietors as well as families that benefited from the land reform, constituted 51%cfi'the rural families. Their 334 holdings are up to 50 hectares (Plan and Budget Or.,1974). From the size of the landholding, this class of the peasantry consisted of three strata: the first group owns less than 2 hectares land; the second one owns between 2 and less than 10 hectares; and the upper stratum owns between 10 and 50 hectare. Table 13.4 shows the situation of these three strata of independent peasants. Table 13.4: Independent Producer Peasants After 1362 Land Reform. w Size Total Areas Percentage Total No.0: Penny Percentage Average eize finecteree) Lhectaree) Area of. Country Peru Unite (h_ectaree) Under 2 785.800 4 .5 1 9056,466 ‘3 I 0.? 2-)10 4,686,305 28.5 969,526 39 4.8 10950 7,500,741 45.5 428,086 11 $7.5 Total ' 12,972,846 “78.5 2,454,066 99 5.3 Source: bitumen-y of Agriculture, 1975. Table 13.4 indicates that Iran has a high proportion of small farms. At least one-third of Iran's present farms are too small to provide the target income if they represent its only source. Since 7 hectares were accepted by Iranian agronomists and rural sociologists as the minimum average amount of land required to support one village family of five members at a basic subsistence level for one year (Hooglund, 1981:93), it is obvious from the above table that 335 at least half of the independent peasants were below the line of minimum subsistence. As we already know, at least 75 percent of those who acquired land under the land reform received less than 7 hectares. The peasant family is the basic unit of production. The field work is done mainly by the members of the family,although in some cases (mostly upper stratum) agricultural laborers are hired for harvest time. Juridically the head of the family is the owner of the land which he received after the reform. Agricultural activities are directed and controlled by the head of the family; the father is normally the director of the enterprise. All production decisions are made ”by him. Independent peasant households control and manage. their means of production,thus allowing them a measure of autonomy vis-a-vis other classes. Independent peasant families are involved in various agricultural activities including farming, livestock rearing, orchard gardening and domestic industry. The production of crops in the units based on family farming is determined by the needs of family consumption. They usually cultivate more than four crops. According to the Statistical Center of Iran, in 1975 more than 7 % of peasants were reported as cultivating more'than four crops (1974). Since there is a difference in terms of various agricultural activities which determine the main source of family income, we can distinguish three main categories. In those independent peasant 336 communities in which the main activity is farming, only 55% of their incomes comes from cultivation; 50% from livestock rearing; 10% from gardening; and 5% from others (i.e., home industry). In the community with predominantly gardening activities, 60% of the independent peasant’s income comes from gardening; 50% from farming; and 10% from other activities. Finally, in a community with sayfi Ear} (summer crops), almost 70% of the income comes from summer crops; 10% from farming; 10% from livestock rearing; % from gardening, and the remaining 5% from other activities (Khosrovi, 1979:100). It was believed by Government Officials that land distribution would encourage peasants to increase their production but, as we have seen, during the land distribution period, the most productive land was allocated to the land- owners and mostly unirrigated and poor lands were redistri- buted among the peasants. This had an effect on independent peasants' income. Another factor which inhibited the efficient use of land was the land parcelization created by the land reform (Cf. Ghorayshi, 1981:29). This in turn affected the income of the families. Although there is no comprehensive information about the level of income of the independent peasant families before and after the land reform, various studies show a tentative level of their income after the reform. According to the findings of the Rural Research center of Tehran University, during the middle of the 1970s, the range of the average income of independent peasant families 337 in Iran was from 6,967 rials in Birjand to 48,682 rials in Kashmar (Ashraf, 1975:41). Table 13.5 illustrates the average income and loan distribution for independent peasant families across the country in 1975. As we can see from Table 15.5, in many regions the average peasant is chronically in debt because his subsistence farming does not provide for any saving margin. The little credit that the lower strata of independent producers could obtain was spent mainly on their immediate consumption need or to repay old debts and, therefore, did not go for the purchase of agricultural inputs from industry (Ghorayshi, 1981:29). As the independent peasant family is unable to really increase its level of living substantially with such poor resources at its disposal, it continues to provide a minimum subsistence income to its members. Since land has begun to lose its importance as a main source of income, the peasants are forced to seek complementary sources of income elsewhere. The vast majority of thses independent peasants worked either as part-time wage laborers in agricultural production outside their own land or migrated as seasonal laborers to cities. Capitalist producers in agriculture and cities benefited from this semi-proletarianization by paying a wage which is below the cost of maintenance and reproduction of the labor force, since the function of the independent peasant sector is to add the necessary complement. In fact, the independent peasants are an inexpensive labor force for the process of capitalist accumulation. 338 Table 13.5: Average income and loan of an Independent producer Peasant in 1975 (Rirals). Regions Income Loan allocated Ilam 19,809 15,520 Bojnord 19,457 12,461 Tabas 15,522 11,546 Kashmar 48,683 5,372 Bandar Abbas 30,568 18,558 Torbat Hidarieh 26,554 10,657 Khalkhal 18,025 7,748 Birjand 6,967 4,672 Nishabor 10,525 14,941 Torbat 28,881 9,856 Dargaz 27,881 15,272 rohan 50,578 10,657 Mashhad ' 32 , 297 8, 506 Source: Ashraf, 1975:40. The consumpticn pattern of the independent peasant families in Iran is representative of a consumption pattern in poor societies. Between 70% to 80% of their income goes for food consumption while there is evidence of malnutrition I among them (Statistical Center, 1972). According to one survey 55% of the loans obtained by the poor independent peasant families has beeen spent on food consumption (Institute of Social Research and Studies quoted in Khosrovi, 1979:24). A large number of peasants actually had to sell 339 their land in order to clear their debts (0kazaki,1968:45). Although the independent producer peasants consume most of their products, they have to sell part of their produce to procure those goods they do not produce themselves and to pay back the usurers from whom they have been borrowing (Halliday, 1981:51). Peasants not involved in the market as sellers of their produce obviously find it difficult to participate in the commodity markets as buyers of the products of industry. On the other hand, many of these peasants who do not sell any of their agricultural produce own plbts of land that are too small to support their families and, therefore, must take whatever employment they can find. In short, the land reform encouraged the growth of market relations and resulted in commodity relations, although they are not ubiquitous. Finally, I should indicate that since the independent peasants are legally and socio-economically attached to their small plots of land by means of ownership rights, they have very little chance for expanding their activities within the village framework and cannot easily leave the village because of their relations to their means of production (i.e.,land). The effect is that the independent peasant household is forced to overexploit its own labor to a great degree. But this has its own limitation. In short, the state that created the many small independent peasants at the same time created many barriers to their viable operation. 340 13.7. Changes in Non-farm Independent Production The non-farm independent sector covers a wide range of activities which supplement agriculture and animal husbandry and are an integral part of the rural economy. They include processing, manfufacturing and infrastructure building. This sector of the rural economy has been under pressure since the penetration.of capitalist activities in Iran. But, after implementation of the land reform, the non-farm independent sector started declining. This pattern has been observed in other countries, too. As Dhamija (1976:70) has indicated, "the neglect of the non-farm sector occurs in most countries whose Agrarian Reform is introudced." Information on employment in the rural non-farm sector is generally unreliable and incomplete.3 According to the Iran Handicraft Organization, 752,000 people were involved in the crafts in the rural area by 1966 census. A majority of them were employed in carpet weaving (71.2%), of which 70% of them were women (Ministry of Interior,1966). The important factor which has to be taken into consideration is the twofold process that is effecting the Iranian idependent crafts workers. 0n the one hand, some . crafts could not compete with modern industrial goods, therefore they start to either disappear or to be diverted to other skills. On the other hand, independent crafts workers (like carpet weaver) who went under a heavy attack from capitalist penetration in their field had to adapt to the needs of the capitalist. 341 Since the traditional artisan could not compete with modern industrial goods, the gap between the quality of local products and mmdern industrial goods grew and the earnings of the self-employed artisan shrank. They found that the goods produced in urban centers or imported from foreign countries coming into the rural market were taking away their clientele. For instance, the development of the plastic industry, which manufactures containers, storage jars, sandals, etc., has put a lot of the pottern workers,metal workers and traditional slipper making industry (givgh) of smaller self-employed artisans out of work.Those who tried to resist faced an increase in the cost of raw materials. The only thing they could do was to cut back on their own earnings. This led to a state of stagnation in most of the sectors and "the younger generation were not interested in entering into traditional crafts" (Dhamija 1976:26). Part of the responsibility for stagnation in some craft sectors was the destruction of the 22228 system. As I discussed earlier, the rural blacksmith and carpenter were directly linked to the activities of the bunehs. Getting free from working within the frame of buneh, the new independent peasants were not obliged to deal with the rural crafts workers. They now could go anywhere to shop or fix their instruments. In addition to destruction of the bunehs, the establishment of the rural cooperative societies not only did not save the operation of artisans like carpenter, but 342 in reality sped up their destruction. As we know, the formal credit system of the rural cooperatives could not be used since the credits were limited to indpendent peasants only. On the other hand, the cooperatives increased a massive flow of the goods from urban to rural communities. These goods were more attractive to the peasants than things prepared by village craftsworkers. As a result of changes in using some means of production (things like water-pump and in some cases tractor and so on), and introduction of new transportation means (i.e.,bicycle and motorcycle), many of the local artisans and some manufacturers had to be diverted to other skills (Dhamija, 1976z5). Shops like garages and bicycle-shops Started to emerge. This was due to the fact that there was a growing local demand for these skills. These shops were totally dependent on the urban market for their parts and material. There was no relation between them and village blacksmiths (if they survived). There were areas in which the situation was totally different. In the case of carpet weaving, the independent producers became totally dependent and subsidized capitalist activities. As we know, the carpet industry has two separate but interrelated sectors. First is the sector which provides and processes the raw materials and prepares them for weaving. Second is the sector which involves weaving itself. Processing of raw materials, which had an important 343 impact on the rural economy, went under heavy attack from capitalist penetration. Wool was the most important of the processing activities,a large proportion of the rural population being greatly dependent on the wool produce. After the land reform, wool producers became the target of the traders. Producers took loans from the traders against the sale of wool during the shearing seasons. For this loan they were charged 40% to 60% interest. They returned the loan in wool and the price paid by the trader was generally 10% to 20% lower than the price paid in the towns. They lost nearly 50% of the value of the wool at this stage. Since they were in constant debt to the trader, they had no choice but to deal with the trader (Dhamija, 1976). The traders now have a monopoly over the raw materials. The independent carpet weaver has to buy the material from them. The trader gives the raw materials on loan. When they buy the spun and dyed wool from the traders, the processes having been done by mills or small workshops, they often pay a price 10% to 20% higher than the market price (Dhamija, 1976:61). The trader or shop keeper also advances the day to day needs of the independent family. They also have control over some aspects of production like suggesting a marketable design for the carpet. after the carpet is ready, it is evaluated and the price is paid to the weaver by the trader after deducting the credit given to the weaver. There was a large complex of Iran carpet Company which was financed by the government in order to help the independent 344 carpet weavers. The company had offices in all at the provinces and also in the districts. The yarn was processed at a central place and distributed throughout the country. Finished goods were also collected and brought down to the central office where they were washed before they were marketed locally or exported. This company was not able to cut the influence of the traders and middlemen since according to official statistics only 4% of the actual production and trade in carpets was handled by the company and the rest was handled by private trade (quated in Dhamija, 1976:68). With expansion of the capitalist carpet weaving looms in the rural areas, the independent carpet weavers are facing another threat. After the land reform, second and third sons of peasants have been forced off the land and are willing to become weaving apprentices (English,1966:81). The capitalist owners of the carpet looms took advantage of these cheap laborers in order to produce more and cheaper carpets. As a result of this new trend, the independent carpet weaver faces competition with capitalist products. In short, the indpendent carpet weavers are more closely linked with urban life than the agriculturalists. Market prices of wool and dyes, current wages for carding, spinning, and dyeing wool, and the international export trade in Iranian carpets are of far greater concern to them than the advent of the spring rains or the condition of this year's crops. In fact, they face an unsafe read to their future, like their counterpart in agriculture. 345 13.8.Endnotes 1. According to some case studies, many of the peasants had [\3 e \N e to hire more experienced peasants for specialized tasks and it caused delay in agricultural activities (Cf. Azkia, 1971 . The Agricultural Cooperative Bank, under the superivision of the Ministry of Cooperative and Rural Affairs, had more than 200 branch offices distributed throught the country grouped into 10 regional subdivisions (Ashraf, 1977:33). For factors responsible for unreliablity of the data on employment in the rural non—form sector see Dhamija, 1976: 32~33. CHAPTER FOURTEEN GERMINATION OF THE INDIVIDUAL CAPITALIST FARM ENTERPRISES 14.1. Introduction During the period of land redistribution, precapitalist muzara-eh and muoata-eh relations of production were definitively liquidated in Iranian agriculture and the large feudal landholdings were broken up. The independent peasant share of total cultivated land increased. However, in spite of this extensive redistribution of land to the peasantry, large individual capitalist farm enterprises were to emerge. It was almost impossible to find a peasant capitalist farming across the country before the 1962 land reform. The peasant capitalist farm is in fact a new phenomenon which emerged as a result of the land reform. Economically, the land reform and other rural "development” programs were designed to benefit only the upper classes in the rural areas. 0n the other hand, the situation after the reform led the privileged sector of the village to accumulate wealth and expand their holdings. At the expense of the poor stratum of the peasantry, a minority group of the rich villagers constituted a class of capitalist peasants. As I discussed before (chapter 7), the large-scale farming 347 based on the capitalist mode of production had developed on a limited scale in a particular region, under very special circumstances, before the land reform. What was unique about the land reform was that it allowed some absentee land- lords to keep some of their lands if they changed their method of cultivation and consequently the relations of production. The land reform benefited absentee landlords by exempting their lands partially from redistribution, and by helping them to establish the capitalist farms. The land redistribution and its related measures has had a significant effect in the development of these farms. By the end of the land reform program (1972), a new rural bourgeoisie and a new proletariat were created in the rural society. In agricultural activities the bourgeoisie's members include those members of the previously better-off peasantry, gavbands, and village headmen (kadkhudas), who have became owners too, and some of the old landowning ’families who have in one way or another retained land, or former middlemen who usurped lands from the peasant-owners through the credit activities. On the other side is the new rural proletariat which is made up of the laborers of pre-reform times, plus those families who might have acquired land but were averted from doing so, or who obtained land and then lost it as a result of a mistake in the distribution policy. This structure was both initiated and sustained by the state which not only created the new legal basis for property rights, but also controlled the system economically 348 through its control of rural institutions. 14.2. Peasant Capitalist Farming The development of peasant capitalist farming after the land reform was mainly due to a variety of economic factors. The first factor was the inequality in distribution of land. This had two significant effects on the process of the emergence of capitalist peasants. On the one hand, a group of the peasants received more land than others, there— fore, they were able to accumulate wealth in one way or the other. On the other hand, the majority of the peasants received insufficient land: this led to the low productivity of the poor strata of independent peasants and consequently some of them sold their land to rich peasants. This led latter to expand their activities. The second factor was the governmental policies which were in favor of the rich peasants. The presence of cooperative officials in the villages in alliance with the richer peasants created credit policies which helped to consolidate the new rural bourgeoisie. The richer peasants had more access to the credits. In fact, it was the intention of the government to help the richer peasants. The third factor was the effect of the capitalist entrepreneurs‘ activities in agriculture on the rich peasants. In some regions (i.e., Gorgan and Moghan dashts), the expansion of capitalist farming has affected the agricultural structure of the regions. An important example has been the 349 adoption of mechanized farming by independent peasants. The development of mechanization had an important role in the alteration of farming methods. The other change was the rapid increase in cultivation of cash crops (i.e., cotton cultivation by peasants in the Gorgan region). Owing to the effects demonstrated by the entrepreneurs' activities, some of the independent peasants adopted the new methods based on mechanization. The richer stratum started to grow cash crops and introduced other new techniques such as irrigation. This led to a change in their financial position, and they could accumulate some wealth, enlarge their holdings, use agricultural laborers and become capitalist peasants (Azkia, 1980: 125-4). On the other hand, some of the middle stratum of the independent peasants who invested in machinery by borrowing credit from various middlemen did not succeed in introducing farm machinery for various economic-technical reasons (i.e., maintenance of the tractor, or paying back the loan on time). Some others who had changed their crops from grain to cash crops suffered from other difficulties (i.e., they could not pay their loan installments ). Consequently, many peasants who obtained land through land reform had to sell their land to wealthier peasants in order to pay their debts (Abedini, 1977:55). This was another factor contributing to the expansion of the capitalist peasants in Iran. The Iranian capitalist peasants consist of former small 350 land-owners, some of the rural elites (i.e., kadkhuda), former landlords' bailiffs, the heads of the production teams (sarbuneh), providers of the oxen (gavbands), and some well-to-do nasaq-holders, whose economic position gave them a influential role in both land redistribution and accumulation of land after the land reform. This class of peasants possess large holdings, between 50—100 hectares, and are incumparably better supplied with productive means than other peasant classes (Ministry of Agriculture, 1975). They constitute a small proportion of the proprietor families (0.6 per cent). The total number is 16,269 families. Their total cultivated lands are 1,075,697 hectares (6.5% of the total in the country). The average size of their farms is 70.5 hectares. They hold 5.4% of the irrigated lands and 4.2% of the rain-fed ones (Ibid.). Their farm sizes are generally smaller than commercial farms. The capitalist peasant and his family members usually do not perform any manual labor but merely manage and supervise. The management is more direct, compared to commericial farms. The capitalist peasants are dependent regularly upon exploitation of the rural wage laborers. They employ laborers on a daily wage basis. They are also dependent upon the poor stratum of independent peasants as a source of seasonal and part-time cheap labor. The subsistence production of the semi—proletarian peasants reduces the reproduction costs necessary for the maintenance of this semi—proletarianized, peasant labor force. As Ghorayshi has indicated, the restricted development of capitalism in 351 rural areas limited the employment of wage labor (1981:30). The point to be mentioned here, in relation to employment of wage labor, is that although peasant capitalist farming has developed in Iran through the past two decades, the social relationship of production still retains some pre-capitalist elements. For example, as A kia has demonestrated, the duration of the workday sometimes exceeds 10 hours; part of the wage may be paid in kind rather than cash; laborers are not allowed to seek outside work in the off-season on penalty of losing their employment; and the majority of the peasant laborers who are hired on the farms use the labor of their own family members in their work (1980:125). My intention here is to present some of the principal characteristics of Iranian capitalist peasants. First of all, they will tend to cultivate their lands themselves rather than give them out on lease. The head of the family is the manager of the enterprise. Secondly, they use hired labor in a much greater proportion than family labor. They usually prefer to employ semi-proletarian peasants since their wages are lower. Thirdly, the fundamental aim of buying the labor power is augmentation of their capital, that is accumulation and reinvestment of surplus value in order to generate more surplus. In short,they tend to so organize their production as to yield a high rate of return on their investments. Fourthly, they would tend to use farm machinery. Since mechanization of farming in Iran is a 352 relatively post~reform phenomenon, the present situation in the peasant capitalist farms is the use of machines side by side with traditional implement (i.e., the capitalist preasants use machines on part of the land while their hired semi~ proletarians use traditional implements) (Golabian, 1977:192). Finally, the capitalist peasants are market-oriented. They produce for the commercial market within a monetarized economy. They would tend to market an important share of their produce. They keep track of the price flunctuation and the demand of the market. The capitalist peasants dominated the water resources and controlled the distribution of water in most villages. This was either through the control of traditional resources (i.e.,qanats), or through the establishment of new irrigation resources (i.e., wells with water pumps). For this reason, they controlled the economic life of the villages (Khosrovi, 1979:88). Since they had more access to water resources, they could use twice as much fertilizer as independent peasants (Aresvik, 1976). They used biochemical technology because it is land-saving, increases yield, and reduces unit cost for the individual producer. The capitalist peasants usually received improved seed from the governmentalinstitutions. As Aresvik has shown, high quality certified wheat seed was Produced by the Seed and Plant Improvement Institute and distributed under the Wheat Impact Program to capitalist peasants (1976:151). 353 In relation to the use of the improved seed, the capitalist peasants were the most frequent users of the technical assistances. The government sold tractors, combines, a-d farm equipment on easy terms through the Farm Machinery Development Department, Ministry of Agriculture, which had sales offices in each province.1 In addition, agricultural machinery was sold through private dealers (Aresvik, 1976:166). Since capitalist peasants were the only group of peasantry which had extra money, they were able to buy most of the machinery offered to the peasants. In 1972 the total number of agricultural four-wheel tractors was estimated at around 25,000 in the horsepower range from 55 to 75. Two-wheel tractors were gaining popularity especially in Gilan and Mazanderan provinces. In the same year, there were 16,789 two-wheel tractors in Iran (Ibid., PP. 162,164). In addition, in 1972 there were about 2,000 self-propelled combines and 15,000 motorized backpack sprayer-dusters (Ibid, P. 168). On the average,each capitalist peasant had one tractor in 1972. Some capitalist peasants whose land was not large enough to fully employ their machinery began to do custom work. This was another source of income for the capitalist peasants (Okazaki, 1968:56). As a result of using machinery, biochemical technology, improved seeds, and water at a proper time, the production 't for capitalist peasants is relatively higher than for independent peasants. Consequently, the capitalist 354 peasants' income from each hectare is higher than the peasant using traditional methods of cultivation. These factors, in addition to the factor of wage labor and the size of the holding, led the capitalist peasants to produce a significant surplus. Table 14.1 shows production of different crops per hectare in peasant capitalist farms for 1978. Depending upon the type of crop predominant in each farm, and in relation to the size of the holding, the capitalist peasant's income varied from region to region in the country. For .instance, production of rice is more profitable than suger-beets. Comparing two capitalist peasants with equal farm size, the one who cultivates rice could accumulate more wealth than the one who cultivates cotton, while both crops are labor intensive. Table 14.1: Gross Income From Some Agricultural Production Per Hectares in 1978 Types of crops Average - Price per Gross Income ‘ Production Kilogram Per Hectare Per Hectare (Rial) (Riral) g(kg.) Wheat 718 14 10,052 Rice 2770 75 207,750 Cotton 1700 29 49,500 Suger-beets 25000 _ 3.4 85,000 Source: Khosrovi, 1980:19. Capitalist peasants, as I mentioned before, produce their products as commodities. The fact that they produce 355 commodities does not differentiate them from independent peasants, but rather the fact that being a commodity is the dominant and determining characteristic of their products. Although they hold only 6.5% of total cultivated lands of Iran, they provided 45.2% (50215 million Rials) of marketed agricultiral products in the country for 1975 (Khosrovi, 1979:109). This shows that their direct aim and determining motive of production is the production of surplus value. One of the results of the land reform program has been a change in the pattern of marketing agricultural produce. Capitalist peasants are now taking no responsibility for transport and sale of crOps, and their activities in this direction have been facilitated by the urban wholesalers who buy the capitalist peasants' products and sell them in urban markets (Thompson, 1976:252). In this regard, there are some disadvantages for capitalist peasants. In summary, peasant capitalist farming is a post- reform phenomenon in Iran. It is expanding as an economic result of the land reform. This type of enterprise.is replacing the old method of exploiting share-croppers and landless villagers, by hiring the semi-proletariat and proletariat of the villages. Since one of their aims to accumulate more land, they are always covetous toward the lands of the poor peasantry. Although they provide a high proportion of the marketed supplies, they are not the main indigenous source of urban food supplies. They produce 356 mostly cash crops like cotton and suger-beets. Before the 1979 Iranian revolution, they had political power over the rural institutions. Although they have not been eliminated from the rural power structure, their political dominancy over the peasantry has been limited. 14.3. Commercial Farming (Capitalist Farming) As I discussed before (chapter seven), prior to the lane reform, except for Gorgan region, one does not find any region in which commercial farming was practiced. The development of capitalist farming after the land reform mainly is due to a variety of economic factors. First, during the land reform, a large proportion of agricultural land was classified as mechanized land and was excepted from the implementation of the land reform law. Some of the former landlords who exempted their mechanized land advanced more mechanization and heavy investment in irrigation. Secondly, the agricultural development policies seemed to be guided by an attraction toward the capitalist model of agricultural development Which stressed widespread mechanization and large financial investments. Thirdly, the large landowners who survived, converted from grain crops to cash crops because of better market conditions for these latter crops. In addition, there was no longer an obligation for land-owners to produce cereals which were necessary as a food-stuff in the old share-cropping system. Finally, the dissolution of the buneh and nasaq systems 357 led to the low productivity of independent peasant farming and consequently the release of peasants from the land, which meant cheap labor for the capitalist farmers. They replaced share-croppers with the employment of a diminished number of dailywpaid wage workers. Commercial farms constitute the economic basis of capitalist farmers which stemmed principally from the former landed elite living in urban areas and from the penetration of merchant capital,politicians' investments, some rich agricultural engineers' investments, and retired army generals' investments into the agricultural domain. They wereall residents of the cities and towns, and they had the full support of the governmental institutions. The most obvious members of the capitalist farmers were the court families. The Shah and his relatives who were among the biggest feudal landowners of the country during two decades before the land reform, turned to the largest commercial farm owners after the reform. The capitalist farm enterprises in Iran have their own characteristics. First of all, these farms mostly belong to one or two individuals who are urban residents (Ashraf, 1975:16). Secondly, they have a relatively high level of capital investment and the use of modern farm machinery are key visages of these enterprises (Azkia, 1980: 117). Therefore, they are usually capitalnintensive. However, labor—intensive crops tend to be grown on some of the large-scale capitalistic farms employing a small highly skilled 358 and privileged group of wage laborers, and a large group of unskilled, poorly paid, and unprivileged workers. The former workers usually are brought from economically more backward areas of the country (Sistan Province) or recruited from the poor population of Afghanistan. Thirdly, the size of these farms is over 100 hectares (Ministry of Agriculture, 1975). These farms represent 0.4% of the country‘s farms (9,553 farms), and 15 per cent of the total agricultural lands (2,452,906 hectares). The average size of the farms is 258.7 hectares. They constitute 18.9 per cent of irrigated lands and 7.6 per cent of rain-fed ones (Aresvik, 1976:102). The fourth important characteristic of the commercial farms is the sale of the labor power by the free laborers. Both native and imported laborers have the mobility of industrial workers (Ashraf, 1975:17). In short, they have a free-floating and mobile labor force. The fifth charac- teristic is that agricultural production is mainly for national, and to some extent, international markets (Azkia, 1980:117). Finally, the management of the farm is the owner‘s duty; he has a representative who is responsible for supervising the agricultural affairs; and he usually has a foreman in the feild (Cf. Ajami, 1977:61). In these enterprises the decision making about using farm implements, investment in technology, supply of land and labor, cultivation of different crops, and distribution of income is the owner's responsibility. 359 Capitalist farming has been situated in rural Iran in three different ways. First, in some villagesthe entire village lands are under capitalistic cultivation. In such villages the class structure is completely polarized: on the one side, the owner and manager and supervisors; and, on the other, a bulk of the agricultural proletariat. Second, in other villages capitalist farms are established side by side with independentpeasant farms or tenancy farming. In these villages the independent peasants remain structurally between capitalist and the proletarian. The capitalist farmers can use the semi-proletariat of the village as a cheap source of the labor. Finally, there is capitalist farming which has developed outside the village boundaries. This can be seen in regions like Gorgan and Torkaman Sahra (Dasht) which started to developed even before the land reform (see chapter 7). In these farms the owners use mostly migratory laborers. The capitalist farms are located mostly in the Mazandaran and Gorgan, Isfahan, North Khorasan, West Azarbayjan, Khuzistan, Fars,Markazi, Kerman, and Fermanshahan regions of Iran, which are known for intensive farming. Even after the land reform, the Gorgan and Dasht regions have the main concentration of capitalist farming units. It is very obvious that the development of capitalist farming in Iran is uneven within each province and between different provinces. T n capitalist farming, there is an exclusive use of machinery. In these farms, draft animals were replaced by tractors; human labor in harvesting was reduced by combines (Okazaki, 1968:38). The enormous impact of mechanization on Iranian rural society is suggested by the following fact: one tractor with one driver and his assistant replaced 45 peasants with 90 oxen (Golabian, 1977:191). This process of mechanization had a deep effect on Iranian rural economy. On the one hand, it not only tended to separated the pea8“nts from the land but also required a division of labor between those who had skills to work the machinery and those who did not. On the other hand, it has of course made the complete separation of livestock and crop farming possible. Before mechanization, the need of producers to maintain livestock for ploughing determined how far this separation could proceed. The capitalist farmers put a large sum of money into farm machinery. While one tractor was needed for every 90 hectares of cotton land, more than one tractor in many cases was introudced for each 90 hectares of cotton land. Usually a tractor of 55 to 65 H.P. was used on the farms. But, some farms have introudced bigger tractors of over 80 H.P. (Okazaki, 1968:22). Since public and private credits were concentrated in the hands of the capitalist farmer, it was easiest for them to buy farm machinery than for the capitalist peasants. In 1972, nearly 50 per cent of all the tractors used in agricultural production were owned by capitalist farmers (Statistical Center of Iran,1972:299). 361- Investment was advanced in irrigation facilities, as well as in farm machinery. As one of the best schemes to raise production was the acquirement of water at a proper time,2 the capitalist farmers invested capital in irrigation facilities. They invested in digging wells 20 to 130 meters deep with pumping equipment. Some farmers adopted a sprinkler irrigation system. Almost all of the capitalist farms had these new irrigation facilities, which required a large amount of capitals. Changes in the irrigation system affected social and economic structure in the rural areas profoundly and fundamentally. As Golabian has indicated (1977:157), uncontrolled sinking of deep wells has damaged the sensitive qanat systems in many areas, decreasing their discharge or even destroying them. There are many reports of villages whose main water sources have dried up after one deep well had been sunk in their catchment zone. Many villages have abandoned by the population just because one rich capitalist farmer (usually a former landowner) sunk a deep well to water his farm, destroying the qanat system of the village and making the continuation of agricultural production impossible. Besides the development of new irrigation systems and mechanization, the capitalist farmers have made extensive use of seeds of good quality and fertilizers. Seeds are obtained either from some factories, i.e., cotton ginning and suger-beets factories, or from a private dealer who 362 usually imported them from Western countries. Since capitalist farmers have the most sophisticated irrigation facilities in the agriculture of the country, they use the highest proportion of the chemical fertilizers. In addition, the introduction of insecticides and herbicides have advanced in these farms. They usually had connection with private and public research institutes. Unfortunately, there is no data available concerning the amount of chemical materials which they have used annually. The labor force in the capitalist farm is fully proletarianized. Since these farms are mainly based upon mechanization, they ”did not absorb a singnificant number of workers” (Ghorishi, 1981230). They usually employed agricultural experts, preferably persons trained at universities or two years colleges, and in a number of instances actually hired foreign technicicans to assume overall managerial responsibility for their farms (Hooglund, 1982:83). In the absence of a production credit system for agri- culture, indicated Aresvik, most of the commercial banks' lending to agriculture was in the form of credit to big capitalist farmers (1976:171). He also showed that the borrowers of the Agricultural DevelOpment Bank of Iran were commerical farmers (Ibid.,p.172). The capitalist farmers. were the only ones who could absorb the long-term credits. is Hooglund has mentioned, the long-term credits were reserved for those individuals with sufficiently large 363 annual incomes so as to be deemed "credit-worthy": the large-scale absentee owners (1981:17). Generally speaking, the capitalist farms usually contain different crops. For example, in the capitalist farms of the villages around Marvdasht in Ears Province, farms with six different crops have been recognized (Cf. Afami, 1977:65). Some capitalist farms produces food— stuff. Some even produce marketable vegetables. For instance, 1.! “n the province of Khuzistan, the urban elite took an interest in marketable vegetable cultivation. In addition to traditional vegetables like onions, leeks, parsley and lettuse, they also grow melons, eggplant and cucumbers. A significant innovation was the post land reform introduction by agricultural engineers of a new variety of watermelon, locally known as hendevaneh-i mohandesi (engineering water- melons)-- the imported Charleston Grad varity (Salmanzadeh, 1980:189). However, in general, the commercial farms are the principal producers of raw materials for industry (i.e.,cotton). In commercial farms, the investment in new techniqes is high because the owners try to conserve labor and fundamentally reduce the cost of production. Their primary objective is to obtain consistently high yeilds and big profits. Therefore, their investment per hectare is higher than the capitalist peasant and independent peasant, certainly. For example, in the village of "Sheshdani" near 364 ’i— Narvdasht in Far Province (which has a typical commercial farm), a farmer cultivating 249 hectares of his land invested 2,473,608 rials which is 9640 rials per hectares. his net income for 1966 was 1,773,575 rials (Ajami, 1977:67). This is incomparable with what an independent peasant could get from each hectare. Table 14.2 indicates the detail cost and net income from each crops per unit, and total costs and benefits for the farm under investigation. It has been indicated that throughout the 1970's the capitalist farms' operations were generally successful (Hooglund,1982:85). All commercial farms produced primarily for the market, and therefore were responsive to such normal market forces as prices of products and inputs, availability of inputs, and market outlets. They were also susceptible to the overall investment climate, and the development of this sector, therefore, was closely related to the national and sectoral policies as they affected the private sector. Capitalist farms, during 1970s, only made a small contribution to the agricultural output of Iran (Aresvik, 1976:100). Their total share of sales of products in the market for 1975 was 4,462 million rials (4.1%) (Khosrovi, 1979:109). They actually played an important role in providing non-food marketable agricultural products. To sum up, the development of capitalism along the commercial road transformed pre-capitalist estates into large-scale capitalist enterprises. Its development 365 I/III-l ‘ ‘ jjillllllll'l] . Ivfi'IIui IN.- I}? l .f . ti [Earrillllur‘llllull . ...-.71 .smuesm..asafla "oonzom o.oo+ mam Hence ooo..~ OOV.F. 0mm.m oms.m o.a v mom cog.mm ooN.em 0mm.v oom.v N.m m xdda ooe.mmw oom.o.m cmm.sm Nmo.m N.NF on smegma ismsonaa mos.m0m 0v9._mm woe.ma smm.¢a o.v? mm mpomnswmmzm omm.ama mo..n.m «so.m mam.m m.s. Na samwmm. 6mm.vmo ovm.mvs was.m va.o N.Nm om, smog: Amamaeu. Amamflmv Amampamv museum: pom Amamfizm meoosH :OHpozuonm mo :oaposconm cadaver no pamonma weaves: macho no: Haves pmoo amuoa mo pmoo osoocH so: .vazo noun: cmmm we came .mo:a>onm whom :a mom. ca Emma pmHHmvamwo Hmofimha m SH osoocH #02 one cofipozconm Ho vmoo “N.vF magma 36MB led to the separation of the small producers from their means of production. In the capitalist farm extra economic relations did not exist, and the capitalist farmer derived his power from his economic basis. This power was shared with the nonagricultural bourgeoisie in controlling the state. Generally, relations between capitalist farmers and agricultural proletariat were characterized by mutual suspiciousness and barely concealed hostility. As a result, by the mid— 1971's, significant numbers of commercial farms had begun to hire Afghan laborers because they were much less troublesome than native agricutural proletarians. On the other hand, during the 1979 revolution many of these farms were expropriated by the popular action of the rural proletariats and the poor stratum of the independent peasants. As a matter of fact, many of these farms are still in operation through the country. 14.4. Agricultural Proletariat Families The number of rural landless after the land reform increased rapidly because during the reform's implementation there was a continuous reduction in the number of families possessing land, and an increasing number were pushed into the rank of rural proletariat. The rural workers existed before the land reform, but the land reform caused a sharp increase in them. The sharp increase of the rural 7,74 proletariat was due to several factors. first, the 367 1 mechanization of some farms prior to the reform, and also during the first phase of land reform, enabled some landlords to displace the share-croppers or turn them into casual laborers who were paid in cash or kind. According to official statistics there were about 161,500 households which had not received land but were still working in agriculture (Sazaman- i islahat-i arzi, 1972). The second reason is that under the second phase, many peasants were forced to sell their rights of cultivation to the landlords and work on the land as a wage laborers. hearly 17,157 families had to sell their land to the landlords. Over half of them were in the area controlled by the prime minister Alam (Halliday, 1979:120). The third reason was that in the transition between phases two and three another 192,000 families seem to have failed to convert their tenancies into ownership (Ibid.). The fourth reason is the size of the most plots which peasants received. It should be noted that many peasants could not subsist from their small plots of land. Therefore, many of them were forced to leave the land. In relation to this factor, when a poor peasant turns to a casual worker,all members of the family over 10 years of age turn to rural laborers, because under the muzara-eh system and within khanevar organization of production all the members were working on the lcnd. rinally, the establishment of the farm corporations and ct agri-busnesses contributed to he increase of the rural proletariat by confiscating the land of some villages 368 (this will be discussed in next two chapters). 1. .L t‘b n act agricultural laborers emerged as a distinct class: a landless rural proletariat, whose common charac- teristics are low income, economic insecurity and unemployment. The great majority of them work no more than six months a year (Azkia, 1980:73). Whereas the relation between the pre-reform agricutural laborer and the feudal lord was determined by custom and tradition and there was extra economic relations, that between the post-reform agricultural proletariat and the capitalist farmer is determined solely by mutual agreement, allowing both much greater flexibility. The rural agricultural proletariat in Iran are indeed free insofar as they are not generally tied to particular pieces of land; but, in the absence of real alternative job opportunities, they are effectively tied to agriculture as a main source of livelihood, even though this source gave them only 200 days of employment in the whole year. The rural proletarian.families have formed a reserve labor pool from which independent peasants, capitalist peasants, capitalist farmers and agribusinesses can draw according to their day-to-day re_uirements. There were 500,000 rural proletarian families according to 1972 official statistics (Plan and Budget Organization, 1976). According to the same source, 209,000 individual proletarian were full-time employed and 139,000 were part-time (for provincial data on full-time and part-time rural workers see Table 14.3) 369 (Ibid., pp. 252/10). According to the Eational Census of Population and Housing for 1976, among the population of 10 years of age and above 23,253 males and 1,567 females were seeking work, and they were previously employed. At the same time, 127,310 males and 10,127 females were seeking work and they were previously unemployed (Plan and Budget Organization, 1981:xL). The high amount of seasonally unemployed males (415,445) and females (196,001) have been reported from rural areas among the active population (Ibid.). Due to th; insufficient size of the independent peasant landholdings, half of the rural proletariat tend to be individuals that do not support families (i.e., sons of small independent peasants). They are related and thus fail to reveal the permanence of linkage to subsistence agriculture. is a result, many wage workers who are members of households partially supported by subsistence agricultural production falsely appear as proletariats. Capitalist producers benefit from this semiproletarianization by paying a wage which is below the cost of maintenance and reproduction of the labor force. Prior to the reform, the agricultural workers were not worse off than the nasaq-holders; but after the land reform the situation of agricultural proletariat has become worse. Their positions deteriorated vis-a-vis that of the villagers who obtained land. Faced with so many problems in selling their labor power, the mass of the rural proletariat had 370 to be satisfied with their marginal life. Consequently, relations between the rural proletariat and independent peasants (especially lower stratum) have been based upon an economic competition characterized by tension and even hostility (Lambton,1966:201). This tension emerged as a result of two facts. First, the middle and upper strata of the independent peasants can under take all the work on their land, therefore they actually eliminated work opportunities on as much as 25 per cent of the land upon which agricultural workers acquired seasonal jobs before the reform. Secondly; since the lower stratum of the independent peasants cannot support their family, they seek opportunities in the capitalist enterprises which as a result keep wages down (Hooglund, 1982:97). In order to survive and continue producing,the agri- cultural proletariat received the minimum necessary for their basic needs. According to official statistics, the average daily income of a male proletariat in 1972 was 98 Rials for a female (Plan and Budget Organization, 1976: 252/11). Table 14.3 shows provincial wages for.male and female separately. This table indicates that except for Boir Ahmad province, the wage for males is twice that for females in almost all other ones. As we know in some areas like Gilan, the women's work in agricultural fields is heavier than men's work. It is obvious that the annual income for an agricultural proletarian family differs from place to place, depending on the prevailing natural 371 I 4 Table 14.3: Distribution of Agricultural Proletariat and their Wages in Iran for 1972 Provinces Full-time Part-time Hen fla,es Women Wages Workers Workers (Bialg) (Rials)_ ,_g Central 11,000 21,000 130 61 Khorasan 23,000 9,000 ' 77 35 Isfahan 13,000 2,000 118 59 East Azer- bayjan 15,000 9,000 104 51 Khozistan 5,000 2,000 87 52 Mazandaran 21,000 33,000 100 58 Fare 15,000 9,000 93 48 Gilan 34,000 6,000 112 62 West Azer- bayjan 11,000 7,000 114 52 Kerman 8,000 12,000 76 38 Kermanshahan 7,000 4,000 115 60 Saheli 1,000 1,000 70 39 Sistan-Balo- chistan 5,000 8,000 56 40 Kordestan 19,000 5,000 99 45 Hamedan 9,000 2,000 136 61 Lorestan 3,000 1,000 119 58 Zanjan 2,000 2,000 100 56 Yazd 3,000 .900 88 42 Boshehr . Charmahal 3,000 2,000 105 71 Semnan 1,000 800 97 4O Ilam 200 500 100 41 Boir-Ahmad 600 1,000 77 72 Country 209, 000 139 . 000 98 55 Source: Plan and Budgent Organization, 1976: 252/10-11 372 conditions, from type of work done, and from ent rpri to enterprise. However, the average annual income was 26,800 Rials, which 18,000 Rials of that was earned from the work of the head of the family, and 8,600 from other memebers (Ajemi, 1977:122). The situation of the migratory labo orers is worse. ilt nough they may earn the same wage as the local proletariat, the double cost of living (one in the host village for themselves, and one in the donor village for th ir families) reduced their living standard compared to the local proles tariat. In fact, they have to migrate since their labor supplies do not have any demands (SMDK, 1978:94). Although the income of the agricultural proletariat has increased compared to the period before the land reform, this increase does not mean an increase in their real income. From 1965 to 1973 the proletarian families' expenses have been raised twice, while there was not an equal increase in their incomes (see table 14.4 for the increase in the rural a- family's expenses). if we assume that ho h the head of the proletarian family and his wife were working for 200 days a year, their average income for 1972 would be 55, 080 rials, while at the same time their average living expense according to the official sources was 59,280 rials (calculated H, Irom table 14.3 and 14.4). This indicates that these families were always in debt to he village sho op} ceeners. The pattern of money spending for the agricultural proletariat in Iran is similar to the poverty pattern, since 373 .wem "whmr .:0H98na:8muo prpzm new soda "chasm v.msom n.0vmv «.mmma o.meav o.smmn m.m00v m.mmnv m.mmmn m.mm>m mmmnmaxm Hopes w.eavm s.mosp m.mmsa a.mmma m.mmma m.e~vF v.mmo. F.8mma 8.0mma mamaoaxm mfiig .850 m.omwm o.wnmm n.mmam m.omsm F.Fnom m.ommm V.VN>N v.mmmm m.mamm memeuaxm ooomnoa use poem mama mama Fem. osma mama mama pom? mama mama momcmaxm no mass Am_u_aa mam—-msm_ .msee on roe s__5sm _mr=m a as umcmaxm a=_>_n mamru>< "¢.¢P apnea 374- they spend a high proportion of their income for food. There is actually nothing to be used for educational or health expenses. Buying luxury goods does not have any meaning for them. ihe only time they take a trip is when they look for jobs outside their villages. Members of the family may not see a town unless they are forced to migrate to the big cities. In these cases they usually become residents of a shanty town. Although they are on the edge of a big city, their life conditions become worse than in their village. They usually have no choice of returning to their home village. To sum up, the rural proletariat expanded in Iran drastically after the land reform. Some of them were _former share—croppers. Losing all the means of production needed to sustain themselves, these peasants came to depend on their labor power as their sole source of live- lihood. The new situations in the rural areas did not absorb them completely, as result of the land reform and other agricultural policies of the government. Consequently, they formed a pool of surplus laborers with low job opportunities. They were in conflict with both new indepen- dent peasants and the owners of the new capitalist enter— prises. This class of the peasantry were the most hungry group for obtaining land‘during the 1970s. Although they H; did not constitute a art 0 D‘ effectiv (D 'd the 1979 revolution, they have been sole to confiscate some of the capitalists' 375 land during 1979-1980. Unfortunately, some of them had to return the lands to their owners as a.result of the change in the attitudes of some of the new rulers in Iran towards land ownership. 14.5.Endnotes These tractors- were assembled in Tabrize by a govern- ment-sponsered tractor manufacturing plant of Rumanian Universal tractors and in Arak by the American John Deer tractor plant since 1967 and 1970 respectively. The following difference in yield is observed between i rri ga ated and unirrigated cotton landzirrigated cotton, 2,329 k ., unirrigated cotton, 965 kg. per hectare in Gorgan Okazaki, 1968:22). An artesian w-ell needed on an average 250, 000— 3000 00 Rials (US 33 ,300— 4 ,000) (Ibid., p. 25). 377 CHAPTER EIETEEN THE DEVELOPMENT OF THE EARN CORPORATION 15.1. Introduction National economic planners had repeatedly questioned the economic validity of independent peasant farming since the mid-1960s. Their argument was based on the point that irrigated farming land was very limited (20 million hectares-- 12 per cent of the total 165 million hectares) and thus measures to increase agricultural productivity were essential to national development. In addition, they .believed that farms were divided into uneconomic units as a result of the land reform. The planners suggested that the difficulty could be overcome by the creation of farm corporations. This suggestion was stimulated by the Shah's model for pseudo-modernization of the farming system. In fact, the farm corporation was a third way employed to develop the capitalist system in Iranian agriculture. The farm corporations were fundamentally semi—governmental joint—stock companies. They were apparently modelled on the western types of joint—stock compai_es, except that there were severe limitations on the transfer or sale of shares. The intention of this chapter is first to explain the objectives of the farm corporations from the statements of the officials. Then I try to make evident the hidden or unstated ends of the corporations. The process of the establishment of farm corporations should follow the statement of the objectives since it responded to the real aims of the officials. Secondly, I will explore the state of change in the modes of agricultural production in the villages which were covered by the farm corporations. Finally, as a result of this change in the production process, I will investigate the effects of these new enterprises on the Iranian rural reality. This will bare for us the new class structure in those villages which went under the farm corporations' operation. 15.2 Objectives of Farm Corporations and the Process of Thgir Establishment The objectives of the farm corporation first appeared in the Fourth Five-Year Plan of the country in 1968. It was elaborated later by the Ministry of Cooperation and Rural Affairs (MCRA) as Article One of the Law for the Formation of Term Corporations. The farm corporation had proclaimed the following objectives: (1) to increase the per capita income of the peasants; (2) to increase output by the wideSpread provision of facilities for farm mechanization; (3) to create all possible opportunities for the use of farming machinery and to make the fullest efforts cf 0 establish the most modern methods of operation; (4) to utilize the maximum manpower in the villages; (5) to prevent 379 IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIll---::——————————————v the division of the land into small and uneconomic portions; (6) to increase production through expanding the area of land under cultivation in the region of operations, by making use of infertile, uncultivated and waste land; and (7) to increase the standard of living of the members of farm corporations (NORA, 1971: 20 and 1974). The NORA indicated that the farm corportions' goals would be reached through the following ways: (a) the exclusive and permanent use of land belonging to share- holders; (b) the intensive use of agricultural machinery, treated seeds, fertilizer, pesticides and so on; (c) the planning of labor resources between agriculture and industry by establishing handicrafts and cottage industries in the rural areas which will be able to absorb the surplus labor released as a result of mechanization of agriculture; (d) the eXpansion and improvement of livestock breeding by the construction of hygienic stables, the provision of fodder, and animal disease control which would increase the production of red meat; and (e) finally, the use of the experts availabe which leads to more efficient management of production and marketing (MoRA, 1971,1974). These were the objectives and the ways to reach them which were stated by the Government officials. In order to set up a guide to evaluate'the farm corporations, I propose some hidden objectives of the farm corporations' establishment: first, it was the intention of the government to speed up the process of expansion of the capitalist relations of productions in the rural areas. Tor this purpose the state 380 injected huge sums of capital in villages covered by corpo- rations. Second, the establishment of farm corporations was the safest way to convince the independent peasant to buy agricultural machinery and other modern agricultural implements (the products of the dependent bourgeoisie). Third, it was proposed to enable the state to gain economic and social control over Iran's rural areas. Finally, the expansion of bourgeois activities in the big cities needed cheap casual labor. The emphasis of the farm corporation on mechanization is obvious proof of this disastrous objective of displacement of the labor force from rural areas which was foreseen from the start. This indicates that the areas for establishing the farm corporations were selective. The initial step for the establishment of farm corporations had to be taken by the TCRA. The Ministry looked for a few criteria such as the >-——: potentialities of an area for increasing both water supplies and land under cultivation, the adjacency of the villages to the center of the province, climatic conditions, and the fertility of its soil (NORA, 1968). This indicates that how the areas for establishing the farm corporations were selective. . Theoretically, for the formation of corporations the votes of 51% of eligible members was required. The government's calculation of percentages to ascertain the extent of the majority was not done village by village but over the entire region involved. An uneven distribution of votes meant the sweeping into a corporation of a village with a majority 381 IIIIIIllllllllllll---:::————————————a opposed to the policy (Denman,1975:215). In practice, the establishment of the corporation was compulsory. They were situated v3herever the government felt was suitable for them. By the end of 1976, there were 89 farm corporations in the different regions of the country. These corporations covered 850 vil lla ages with a total 53, 662 members. The total' land under their control was 401,000 hectares of which 590,000 hectares of that were cultivable and only 150,000 hectares were actually under cultivation (ECRA, 1976:151e157). Table 15.1 shows the provincial distribution of these farm corporations with the number of villages covered in each province and the number of share-holders. as table 15.1 indicates, most of the farm corporations were concentrated in the western half of the country which has the most fertile lands and most plentiful water (see chapter Four). The peasants in these areas could have continued farming successfully without introducing farm corporations. ln contrast the eastern half of the country which is the backward area, desert oases, and arid region (all of which badly needed investment and the development of irrigation cili ties) were disregarded by the government. This shows that the policy was on behalf of uneven development. It was the governments' intention to develop capitalist activities in those agricutural areas which were profitable, not to develop the poor underdeveloped regions of the country. 382 Table 15.1: The Provincial Distribution of Farm Corporation in _ 1972 Province No. of Farm No. of No. of Corportions villages Share-holders Markazi 6 70 2,800 Kermanshahan 9 131 3,381 Khuzistan 8 86 2,935 Kerman 6 127 3,806 Luristan 5 26 1,502 East Azar- bayjan 11 65 3,966 West izar- bayjan 6' 54 1,972 Pars 15 116 4,172 Khurasan 5 29 1,666 Charmahal 7 59 2,642 Kurdistan 2 13 704 Hamadan 3 15 931 Sistan 2 20 1,222 Gilan 2 7 577 ‘Mazandaran 1 5 359 Isfahan 1 2 135 Zanjan 1 2 308 Ilam 1 23 604 Total country 89 830 33,662 Source: Ministry of Cooperation and Rural Affairs, 1976: 151-157. ’ 383 The area of a farm corporation could exced 1,000 hectares and could include from two to 20 villages and farms (Salmanzadeh, 1980:226). ihe farm corporationYS agricultural land average was 3500 hectares, not all of which was cultivated (P ahn, 1978: 4). This shows that for the first time in Iranian history the boundary of the village as a complete and integrated socio-economic unit was broken. Table 15.2 gives detailed information about all farm corporations in the Ears province. AS we can see from the table, the two areas of concetrationx(8hiraz and Firuzabad) are the most fertile lands of the province. secondly, it shows how the villages boundaries were borken. For example, the Karzin corporation included 21 villages. Thirdly, it indicates how small proportion of the villagers were the members of the corporations. Financial assistance (read governmental capital) had a very steady role in establishing the farm corporations. or 89 H) According to official reports the value of loans corporation up to 1977 were more than, 1 ,722, 744 Mthousand Rials, and the total gr nts-in— —aid were 8,422 thousand Rials. The loans were for periods of between five and fifteen years, and bore 4% interest per annum. 1% interest, together with the original amount of the loan was repe aid to the government, while the remaining 3m was spent ov T flfl loan on ”develop ment” projects in the farm corportions /a-f~(—\ \nvii,1978). is is obvious, while obtaining credit for rural 384 mac“: ”oohnom mmH+HmH Momma «msflmmm< Henna can :oflpmsomoou mo zap Ill IIIIIIIIIIIIIII —m\N\mN . . . .. .. _m\~\n~ coo.am..~_ mm~.~_ one 8r... mg.N oqm._ aoo.o ooo.a a. m.oo~ u.a-=g.u at d gu_a em\~\m. ooo.~o..~ Nov.“ can o-.~ NM...m. moo.— .Nn.m mac.m a on uaaauagvd «can a. a an mm\Np\wN. OOo.¢S.O~ 30;: ”h §.P GOO.N. 68¢ cmN.N 68.” 2. pp OaAONP-vu “L...— hnMQ mm\~.\v~ coo._mm.mp .mm.m_ — «so._ «on p as... mmm.. Nuo.m m an ugmauo>ng “Lad any“ a om\~_\a— coo._~m.m .Nm.m onN mum _ omm._ om«.— nom.~ an~.o a ~m ugmouo>r~z ug.a =~..ou=u~a ~m\__\~— coo.noa.~ flea.“ sn— ooh. omm.p ace. om... oom.. n n u.4¢~=..d ar.m u.na~=r.a ~m\__\m. ooo.-m.m -m.m new mmo . can“. «so «a~.. nm~.~ h a eaaa~=r.m mr.d =_gn.~>qx ~m\__\._ ooo..~o.~ _~o.~ ..m. mam. m_m._ mom mo~.. onm.~ a ma "snag“ “Lam Loo“ ~35 8o.§.~.8_.2 W: 3... 8a.. m3“. S»... «a... a 8 5:3 cc 53m. ~m\m\¢ ooc.oa¢.~. ca..~_ ~MM can.P ooa.— co.._ oNo._ Nan.m m we , -g.=m “rad =.~uoroa ~mxnxm ooo.~mo.o— smo.op p- smm._ cpv.~ pun p onm.— sue.» a —o Nagvgw “Lam acumen: ¢mp — cm¢ — cam mmm.p m-.n e an Nagasm. mung usuav>uaz maxmxmn coo..c¢.m .ov.o we. .~m . .Na.. No... -a.. m.m.n m we Nansen . “rad .-gmuwunu . . 353 as g ... ~84 3 .9 n8 ...8 as; on... N 3 5...... ca 29:3 a: a: a: saucuaau Am_a_¢v soap» co scans snow :0; who 0 van) flea ...... .....n ...... h.“ an“ ha.“ ha an. an “a 3:... ......a... we mung 50 oz oosagm —uuop nun“ ”fine" so saga mo .02 coca sham we use: pane» .um.a oocw>osa mama cw :owumsomsoo spam mo canyonsum paw :ofiqupom one ”m.mH oases '3535 ’i— cooperatives was difficult, there was no problem for farm corporations since they were in favour of the government. is a result of this governmental investment, the farm corporations were established very fast (see last column of table 15.2). 15.3. Mode of Agricultural Production in Farm Corporations Through the establishment of a farm corporation in,a village, all the production enterprises were transformed into a large-scale capitalist enterprise hiring wage laborers. Membership was essentially confined to villagers who were fitted to the following categories: (1) peasants who received land from land reform, or the pre-reform independent peasants; (2) barzegaran who did not receive land through the land reform; (3) farmers and landowners who for some reasaon (i.e., mechanization) were not affected by the land reform; and (4) tenants who acquired land under 99 year lease of vaqf lands (Rural Research Group, 1970; Richards, 1975:10). Other villagers (i.e., non-agricultural laborers) were not allowed to join the corporation. At the initial stage, the peasants and other landowners transferred their lands to corporations for complete and permanent use; and received in return a share "equivalent" in value to the property contributed. The peasants retained nominal ownership of the land; it was the ”use rights" which, in effect, were deeded in perpetuity to the state, although the government officials did not admit that farm 386 corporations were really a species of "state farm”. Here, it seems that ”land reform gave the peasants title to lend only to take it away from them again” (Richards, 1975:11). The lands of those peasants who refused to join farm corporations were forcibly expropriated. Evaluation of a peasant's means of production (i.e., land machinery, oxen and equipment) was made by a three-member Committee. Corporation Law established no valuation formula, but the general principal was ten times the annual income from land considered the value of land; and there was more flexibility concerning the transfer of machniery or oxen belonging to the peasants. If they were needed for the corporation they would be acquired, but if the equipment was not fundamental for the corporation then they would be referred to as loan to the corporation (Azkia, 1980:150). in average share represented (in 1972) 1,000 Rials (310.31) of the land’s appraised value (Richards, 1975:11). There were three fundamental problems with the process of evaluation of the lands: first, there was no appropriate knowledge about the size of the holding; consequently different shares were given to equal-size lands. Secondly, lands with different qualities were given equal values, therefore,some peasant later complained about this. Finally, the manner of pricing the lands was disputable for peasants. They claimed the land was not priced on its market price (Pourafzal, 1972: 155-158). is a result of this mis—evaluation, >9 the e‘isting share-holding inequality became sharper. 387 —7—— Since the corporation did not limit the number of shares which each member could hold, there was high diversity in the means of production, notably in the amount of land, among the members of each corporation. For example, in oasri-shirin Corporation 140 peasants, each holding less than 15 shares, had 1,242 shares, compared with 32 rich peasants who had 2,764 shares (Keshavarz, 19712141). In other words only 9% of all shares belonged to 42% of peasants while 70% of the shares were allocated to 12% of the shareholders. Or, in the case of Dargazin corporation, 5,000 shares out of a total of 17,000 belonged to 28 former rich landowning families (6%of the total shareholders) while 70% of the remaining shares belonged to 94% of peasants. The smallest individual share-holding was 1.6 and the largest was 1,118 shares (Azkia, 1980:155). in fact, this new institution perpetuated the old economic and political structure in the village in a new manner. The former landowners, village headmen, and gavbands who possessed more shares held more power in the corporations. Their share- holdings were usually above 80 shares. The poor stratum of the independent peasants (holding less than 30 shares) and the landless members of the corporation, who were economically poor, played no role in the power struture of the corporations. Finally, the former nasaq-holders, who were in between in the *pre-reform system, remained in between in new system. Put in Jazani‘s words, ”it was the 388 if number of shares owned by a person that will determine his possession and not his work" (1973:61). The unequal structure of share-holding affected all the aspects of the share-holders' life. Despite the increase in cnrporation-sponsored lending, there were some restrictions on borrowing for some of the small share holders. This meant that small share holders continued to be dependent upon traditional sources of credits which offered short-term credits with high interest rates (more than 40%), in order to support part of their consump- tion needs. However, the medium and large share holders had no difficulty obtaining credits from the corporations, since there was a large amount of money provided annually as loans and grants to the corporations (for example, there were 6,184,511 Rial credit for 33,662 members of farm corporations in 1976 (MCRA,1976)). The value of credits granted to the farm corporations was 20 times greater than in the sector dependent on rural c00peratives (Katouzian, 1981:309). This astronomic difference, which was completely due to the highly discrimi- natory policy of the government in distributing credit and grants between the two sectors, was for the purpose of mechanizing the corporations‘ farming.1is a result, the . corporations invested heavily in machinery without attention to the real need for such machinery.2 The use of tractors in farm corporations rose from 20 per cent of cultivated areas, before the commencement of their operations, to 100 389 *7 percent in the annual cultivation year of 1974-75 (NORA, 1977:63). Consequently, draught animals were replaced by tractors. During the same period the utilization of combines increased from 5 per cent to 95 per cent of the cultivated areas (Ibid.). Human labor in harvesting was entirely displaced by combines. A total number of 652 tractors and 95 combines and over L600 other agricultural tools were distributed among these corporations (Ashraf, 1977:22). Besides heavy investment in agricultural machinery, contract agreement with foreign countries made possible a number of big projects within farm corporations: livestock breeding and related industries with the help of the Yugoslavian Agro-Industrial Institution; chicken production and food factories with the help of the Bulgarian Techno- Export Institution;a computer services project with 24 mini-computers and a terminal in Tehran with American help; a water supply and irrigation network development project with the help of American companies; and finally a management improvement project with the help of FAC experts (noni,1975). All the above—mentioned heavy investment indicates that the establishment of farm corporations meant the eXpansion of markets for foreign goods in the rural areas of Iran. Each farm corporation was a wo million dials annual market for industrial goods and products (SEEK, 1978: 269 . Beside the purchase of foreign goods, every ‘ear the 390 7" MCRA had to pay for the services that foreign eXperts had to supply to the farm corporations. In addition, the international ”experts" on the issue of farm corporations were paid in order to do research on the corporations' "development”. These were other unnecessary expenses which had to be paid by the corporations or the hCRA to the foreigners. The drastic change in landownership and level of the productive forces accompanied with the bureaucratic nature of the farm corporation Organization created a new division ’— 1‘ b o labor in the rural areas when these enterprises were established. The organization of the corporation consisted of a General Assembly of shareholders, a Board of Directors, F‘" Inspectors and a Managing Director.9 Theoretically, policy-making and other geneal business was entrusted to the General Assembly. However, in many corporations peasants claimed that they had no influence in policy-making (Cf. Azkia, 1980: 157-158). The Board of Directors was responsible for the constitution of the General Assembly. Its main duties were to define the problems of the corporation; to prepare the financial report; to supervise the activities of the Managing Director; and finally to decide about the corporation's contract with other agencies (hCiA, 1974). The rich peasants and the village headmen usually occupied these offices (Rural Research Group,1970). One of the shareholders was elected as an Inspector who, 391 ————" ‘0‘ along with an agriculturalist designated by the NORA, was responsible for checking the accounts and helping the implementation of the provisions of the corporation statuses (rcal,1974). Theoretically, a Hanaging Director should be elected by the Board of Directors, but in practice he was appointed by the NORA (Tlan and Budget 0ranization,1968: 114). He had complete power over the farm corporation and was directly responsible to the farm corporation central supervisory unit of ECRA in Tehranr(8almanzadeh, 1980:227). determination of the socio-economic structure of the villages under their control. Some of them had more power than pre—reform village owners. _n farm corporations, labor was supplied by the share- holders and barzegaran who worked for wages. Theoretically, as a result of the farm corporation all the members should become wage laborers. Tn practice since cultivation became greatly mechanized, the majority of the farm corporations could not hire all their members. The Managing Directors were in favor of hiring non-shareholding laborers, since they were ready to work for lower wages (SMDK, 1978: 274). is a result, a few of the share-holders were hired in non- farm activities of the corporations, and the bulk of them remained merely shareholders, with nothing to do except waiting for their annual income from their shares. The source of the income in a farm corporation was either from dividends on the shares, or from wages received 7 as labor services. Net profit of the farm corporation was 392 explained as total earnings after the deduction of expendi- ture and depreciation.a minimun of 15% of net profit was regarded as retained profit and was put in the reserve fund of the corporation for contingencies. After all deductions were made, the balance was distributed among the shareholders on the basis of their shareholdings (Frevialds, 1972:187). The profit was in the interests of those who owned relatively large plots of land, not the peasants who cultivated their own small plots of land. With reference to wages, wage rates varied by the levels of responsibility, type of work and productivity of workers as determined by the Manager and the Board of Directors (Richards, 1975:11). There was a tendency in corporations to pay less wages to the laborers for the same jobs in comparison to other regions of the country (Azkia, 1980: 233—4). This happened because, as we know, one of the indexes for the ”prosperity" of a corporation was net profitability. In this regard, since the large share- holders did not perform wage labor in the corporation, they imposed low wages on the dependent .peasants who needed jobs to achieve subsistence levels. In order to keep the wage low and reduce the cost of reproduction of the labor force, the wage labor shareholders were given personal user-rights over garden plots up to one thousand square metres adjoining their respective house. According to the reported balance sheets of 53 corporations 393 f 1“!) in 1974, the average annual profit 0 18,605 shar holders was about 5801 and the average annual wage of these shareholders who gained employement in corporations was abo~t 5 426 (Ashraf, 1977:22). We should bear in mind r that the majority of shareholders in each corporation held below.the average shares. Also, not all shareholders were offered jobs in the corporation. In order to show the actual distribution of annual profit in the corporations, I will give two examples here. In the case of the Tivan nar farm corporation near Garmsar, total expenditure for 1969 was 5,457,408 Rials and total income was 5,508,896 Rials. The net profit before deduction was 51,491 Rials which after a deduction of 15 per cent (7,723 Rials) as a reserve fund, the balance was 43,768 Rials. Since this corporation had 4,855 shares, the annual profit per share :1) was only 9 ials. With regard to the average number of shares which each shareholder had in that corporation (30 shares), the average annual profit was 270 Rials (SMDK, 19782273). This was the case of a desperate corporation. In the case of the Shamsabad corporation (which was regarded as the most successful corporation) in Fhuzistan, the dividend paid per share was 410 Rials (Salmanzadeh, 1980:232). If we assume that the average shareholder held 30 shares in this Q cor oration, the avera.e annual profit per shareholder was 0 1 12,300 “ials. Even this amount was low compared to the average income of a non-croporate independent peasant. These 394 ”— data from case studies indicate the groundlessness of the governmental claim about t small shareholders of the 1 a before, his landowners who held a larg 1 .4. The Structure 5 Effects of Farm The establishment of whole socio-economic struc under their operation. In production of wheat in corporations was 4 independent peasant family he increase in income of the corporation. As I mentioned system was only beneficiary to the former e amount of shares. Corporations on Rural Sochgl farm corporations changed the ture of the rural societies the sphe e of production, the "3 fig/ I /0 a. higher than the farms. In the case of rice, cotton and barely yield per hectare was 3%, 13% and 9% higher in the corporations for wheat,the variation of increased production, but t development of new water re from this {D corpo corporations and independent very significant. It is true times greater than for a peasant household in then the higher production per as one might have anticipated. (Azkia, 1980:214)._Thus, except yield per hectare between the peasant family farms was not that many corporations be .LL his was mainly through t sources. If we bear in mind that the average farm corporation investment per household was 100 n a cooperative, hectar does not seem as marked Ecwever, someone must ha ve heavy investment. ration's activities o the absentee shareholders who had 0 her occupations in enerated wide difference in ct C) (D O In: CI‘ }.J (D U) C i :3 p (D O O *3 ' C5 0 "5 gm Cl’ l...) O D U) 09 income dis ribution among the peasants and socio—economic 1 differentiation among the regions. In fact the central government was able to take advantage of the class structure existing in the countryside, by reinforcing the position of the well to—do peasants (sar-bunéhs), lessors of productive means ( gavbands), and remainders of the former landowning class. is a result of widening economic differentiation, the nature of the conflict between different peasants changed.Dispute over shareholding caused tension among peasants. Conflict over discrimination in employment and I 1 low dividends caused tension between peasants and the administration. Generally speaking, a conflicting relat n emerged between small shareholders worlu g for wages and non-shareholder wage laborers, on the one side, and the large shareholders and mangerial-technical staff, on the other side. In fact, with the emergence of the corporations, the peasants had to endure new explo Mt tion by the state apparatus. The establishment of farm corporations was very unpopular among the majority of affected peasants. In many cases a confrontation with Government agents concerning the .1. transfer of their exclusive right of cultivation of land to 4 . . the corpor ion emerged. In almost all the cases, after a considerabl (D amount of wrangling peasants realized that IIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-IllllI--———______l demands and complaints would get them nowhere. "To silence their objections, peasants are told the Shah wants the corporation” (Flatt, 1970:80). The insistent peasants were jailed in order to serve as an example for others. One of the consequences of the farm corporation operation was that the peasant was forced to migrate. This was a result of the nature of the corporation. The inequality of holding the shares in the corporation forced the small shareholders to leave the village. Also, the 4.1 disproportionate use of machinery in bfle corporations rendered nearly all the villagers, be they independent peasants or agricultural proletariat, unemployed. For example, in Dargazin Corporation it was estimated that with full mechanization the labor force would be reduced by 80% (Behpour,1971:10). Despite the promises of the corporation to establish the rural industry and handicraft centers, the farm corporations did not provide adequate alternative employment for those peasants who were either self-employed or full-time family helpers. Consequetly, many peasants migrated to the cities looking for jobs. In the case of the Garmsar Corporation, 210 out of a total P!) o 703 shareholders have left the village since the creation of the corporation (Azkia, 1980:156). This consequence was a response to the aim of releasing workers for casual in the cities. \ work Some corporations started to introduce particular cash crops (i.e., opium) which needed specialist peasants. p.397 q Therefore the corporations had to employ agricultural workers from other regions. This created seasonal migration which had a negative eiiect on the ,rosperity of the native workers. In tde case 0: the Garmsar corporations more than 2,000 migrato;y peasants from different part of Khuiasan regularly Research Group, 1969). It was the same in all the corporations which shifted to the new cash crops. One cf the main effects of the corporation programs w s the extension of governmental control over the rural areas through urban bureaucrats. Since the emergence of the corporations, tne peasants were unable to control their ile (1. L5 (D 91: got rid of the former landlords, they came under the control of a new master, namely the state and its bureaucrats. The power was concentrated in the hands of urban bureaucrats in order to prevent a potential peasant movement. One of the most important problems which was created as a result of -arm corporations was the waste of agri— cultural capitai through lack of supporting service and ‘) while awaiting the de l spare part” (Salmanzadeh, 1980:256). It was very obvious that - .. Cl C) (D F6 0) w *3. O O H ‘Lj O s (D c l‘ |._J O D" Q Q) (.0 {D "d (D (D C. p. O I a O Q. (D H '55 'Jp N m (7" |_.J- O .5 O H) Cf L) (D l' 398 system that could expand through the country in isolation. In fact, the aim of the cor po- ti on (higher income for \easants) and the means to reach this aim (mechanization through the introduction of farm machinery) were confused. In Short, the farm corporation program was a state deception to preserve the interests of the former landowners and to expand the influence of the bourgeoisie in tie rural areas. The expansion of capitalist activities by the farm corporation's program not onlyf aile d to solve the agricultural problems of the country, but created a JD I dependency o- agricultural and non—agricultural activities upon foreign countries which provided agricultural machinery and implements, computerized offices, and experts. In machinery, the corporations purchased a lot of im orted tractors and combines without having the capacit v to maintain them. Furthermore, the establishment of a center pivot irrigation system was an inappropriate. irrigation system for the Iranian countryside for the same reasons as the use of machinery; In relation to the use of the computer in office, there was no thought given to the problem of how to operate a computer in rural Iran. in atdition they did not consider how they would find computer programmers to work in rural Iran. Finalli, in relation to experts,many TiC and other international exerts were hired or invited to work in "developmental” planing in order to suppor the government‘s agricultural policies re ted to the farm .1. corporations. 399 if farm corporation programs were continued, we might have disastrous rural areas at the end of the 19803. They would have created anarchy both in the sphere of production and consumption. fortunately, the 1979 Iranian revolution stopped their opertions and emancipated a sector of the peasantry while it offended rich and large shareholders. In this regard, the power base of the urban bureaucrats he villages was eliminated, while the caitalist peasants and farmers started to run their enterprises again. Of course, the independent peasants enterprises began to exploit their family labor as before the establishment of the farm corporation. 400 |\) 15.5.Endnotes 78% of the financial help given to farm corpor rations was in the form of grants (3tem Jogqedam, 1978). 0') For example :ar msar Corporatin had 1 bulldozer,5 jeep 21 tractors, 4 com mbines, 5 furrowers, 4 ditchers, 1 border marker, 6 fertilizer distributors, 20 motorized sprayers, 15* rail are, 2 balers, 1 threshing machine, 1 rake, 4 weldi11ng machines and 21 lorries (Rural Pesearch Group, 1969). *4 N OJ :1- [.1 9 O y- (I L‘i’ (D For detail description corporation see Tahn, 1 \00 —45 (n own I ~45 See the f between C issue of _ 1976; Eajaii, 1 ng works for cases involrins confrontation and the covernvent official over t; mation of CUltiVG tion rights: GOES '; 313K,1978; Azkia, 1980. —\1 [3' O): 401 F17." Pmt‘f) .-.—J- . . e‘ 1 U..-— — T'TTT‘TT‘WT (“‘1 2.) .1. -3. .1. 4.1.1.42: “—TTTfi. "1 " " 211’“ “:1 ('1'- H . n ”3' 'T-‘. f“ 33‘ £1 DTi‘iigii'l OJ: 4.51.1.1 AJRI-DU 8:31.110 0) L11 1 d -+ l -3 :1 F0 ' I} H U) D“) m 16.1. Introduction Word "agribusiness” coincides with the switch to vertical organization on the part of certain giant compaines able to control the whole food chain from field to table. These corporations have what they like to call the ”total market concept" and they are applying it both in the center and in the peripheral countries. In two words, as George says (1977:133), the agribusinesses see themselves as the world's salvation. They think they alone are capable of solving the problem of world hunger. Some agribusinesses involve the setting up of a large- scale (usually over 1,000 hectares) mechanized and capital intensive farming operation. A wide range of commodities are covered by agribusinesses, including grains, industrial crops, fruits and vegetables, red meat, and dairy and poultry products. Other agribusinesses involve both pro—' ducing and processing (in this case, it is referred to as agro—industry). For the purpose of this chapter, I use the term ”agribusiness" to refer to both horizontally integrated farm activities and vertically integrated farming and processing activities. 402 ——i—— The fourth type of capitalist mode of cultivation in Iran was the introduction of agribusiness in rural areas. The development of agribusiness activity in Iran was due to the enormous initiative of the state. The strategy was heavy state investment in infrastructure to create a climate conducive to private investment. It is the intention of this chapter to show how the government facilitated the expansion of agribusinesses in the countr . is a result, the basic aspects which will be analyzed are: the control of the means of production by a sector of the dominant class (in alliance with foreign capital) which had access to large amounts of cash; the transformation of the social ’5 relations of production; and the development or new production techniques which were based on the widespread use of machinery. Finally, the agribusiness activities will be evaluated in order to see their successes or failures. 16.2. Reasons Behind the Agribusinesses and Process of Their Emergence The emergence of agribusinesses in Iran must be related to the internationalization of capital in the H sphere of agriculture. According to the logic of inte p. H) te *‘S |.__l national capital, the United States is best su 0 grain production, and the Third World should therefore produce cheap cotton, tomatoes, strawberries, beef, and poultry, etc., for the united States or Western Europe. 403 *7 This displaces Third World staple foods and thus further creates a market for American grain (Burbach and Flynn, 1980). igribusinesses have several incentives for moving into the Third World. Throughout the world, agribusiness is "zeroing in,” as Bankamerica President Lundborg suggested years ago, on the best land and the cheapest labor in the under-developed countries. Speaking of his company‘s new thrust towards overseas production (in Guatemala, Iran, Indonesia, etc.) Murray Stewart, President of C.Brewer and Co. says, ”we’ve been in this business longer than almost anybody else, so we're interested in anything that can be grown profitably” (George, 1977:151). Agribusinesses have incentive other than cheap labor and high margins for moving into the Third World. Their overall taxes are often substantially reduced for operations in host countries. The agribusinesses are the ones that use a "host" country's land and labor for producing food—-rarely to satisfy local needs, almost always for export to the developed countries‘ markets that will pay the most for their produce. Foreigners have always been important to Iranian "development” projects. There was liberal policy toward the importation of capital and intermediate products, as these were regarded as essential to the successful. q—v‘ implementation of the import—substituting strategy (resaran, 1 Iranian government decided to 82 509). is a result the \I.) bring foreigners deeper into the fabric of the society 404 —’7 (FirtzGerald, 1974:78). To attract the flow of foreign capital to the agricultural sphere of the country, the government had to Cl ea te the necessary conditions for that 1 to occur. In order to discover such conditions, the government of Iran formally entrusted the task of a com- prehensive survey to the Dew lork—based Develpment and Resoruce Corporation (D & P), headed by David 3. Lilienthal and Gordon Clapp (United States, Tehran Embassy, 1957). 7 These two architects of the Tennessee ally authority (TI/4 ) established the hnuzistan Development Service (lDS). The KDS set forth studies, plans and recommenda ons d‘ The most importan recommendation was that 14 dams should eventually be constructed in Khuzistan. Ither recommendations concerned irrigation, land preparation and crop and soil research (Bagley, 1976:28). The IDS was awarded executive authority in the contracting of foreign compaines for the construction of dams and other projects which were considered crit al to agricultural develpment of the province. EDS was to work with the Khuzistan Water and Power Authority (ETTA) to spearhead the necessary techn al fOUI Qdations for large-scale, capitalist ventures in the area. Since most of contracts went to American companies, it is not surprising that by 1957 the IDS was understood to exist primarily as a ”tool for American interests" (United States, Tehran Embassy, 1957). i-$ 511 F] In 1958 the Shah described the panacea for agricultw C1 deve1onment in Zhuzis 'an as —:— The project covers a series of dams and flood control works, and the program is based on the coordinated exploitation of all the resources of the region, by principles of cooperation between public and private groups and agencies on the lines of the Tennessee Vally. This symbolized the threshold of a new era and a unique expansion of industrial development in the middle East (Silsby, 1980238). ;y 1959 the Shah ordere‘ work began at once (Richards, 1975: 13). we should bear in mind that it was after this project that Iran embarked on the land reform. The first dam was Dez Dam. Since the dam was huge and its construction was above the Iranian government’s ‘4) “ancial capacity, the D & R asked the World Bank for A I) iinancial help ior l-I ran. One of the conditions which the World Bank laid down in 1959 for financing the Dez Dam was that a portion of the project be devoted to_a pilot irriga- tion project to demonstrate the benefits of modern farming techniques (Ibid.,p.13). As a result of the state investment and the World Bank financial aid, the ”public works” and the large—scale irrigation projects for Dezful and other areas were systematically advanced primarily to assi in la arge scale agriculture ventures. as Silsby (1980:49), has indicated, it was not the purpose of the government, the agriculture ministers, or the hu’Pii officers to build the De: Dam for indigenous smallholders' needs. From the very begining, la rge- -scale irrigation was conceived as mrely a necessary foundation for future large-scale agri— cultural ventures. In fact, by 1959 when the construction of the Dez Dam began, it was clearly understood that the 406 rri 14 ation system was prepared, in the filter the 09 Ct creation \_/ (1) O 5 d‘ :..J (D Fourth Elan (1968-7 , here was an emphasi 5 of large farming and “nimal husbandry units to be operated ned in O menti HI by advanced techniques (Field, 1972:68). chapter 12, in 1968 the government passed the agribusiness ict as a supplementary measx re to the land refo_l. Br iassing the Aoribusiness not, the national planners showed their desire to introduce modern, large- scale fa; ming systems t into the agricultural sector. The Dez Irrigation Projec l ....D b area was selected exclusively for establishment oi the agr ibusinesses. However, in other areas of the country, the sound of preparing the land and irrigation canals for he policy of agri- ct agribusiness was heard. Accordin o 09 d' business development, agricultural poles were designated and land expropria ted for the injection of capital and sophisticated foregin agricultural enterprises. To mak way for agribusiness the nv?; was permited to ”buy” the land of independent peasants from 58 villases within the project area, usually against the desire of the peasants to part with it (Richard, +975z14 fore, f07ced the villa ers involved on 17th July 196; to ({Q contact the nfl?l oifice in Dezfu IQ d O m m I4 H (“i D m I.) H D‘ O |._J Q ’J S bQ U) to the government.2 Between July .969 and June 1973, the . *_ _ ‘ ‘l_ _ '1 Am “ ' _ m I. .J...‘ a o ‘ f‘ EOvefnmecb "re-purchased” 40,Ub0 heCtares in one LeSlgflGted n r ' ' - 4... .9 4.1 A 4.. .3- /'(-~ .Am ~. _|_ _ areas. ihe remaining parJ ii the total oo,Coo hectares ‘ v - .-,- __ CU‘_DQSS€S Was 30 re-purc"ase d C7 garCh *J. 1 ‘ A I“\ «A --r~-4 r7- alLCCEUCQ iv; cfir 'u 1974 (igro—industry and Settlement Department, 1973). The peasants were compelled to sell their land a administrative prices which were netted ior their debts _" 1 to the state and the cost oi housing accomodations built for their resettlement (Latouzian, 1978:561). ..‘¢_cc01 ding n to the International Bank for Reconstruction and CJ elc ment, for t he initial 22, 000 hectare Dez Project area, 121,000 people in fifty-eig ht villages were expulséd (quoted in Silsby, 1980: 51). _n ey were members of almost 58,000 peasant famililes who just acquired the land as a result of the and reform implementation. 1 structural change took place when the ownerships of large number of independent peasants began to fall into prepare for the .3 o H Q. (D "5 rt 0 o“ a) the hands of the state i- ‘g class and their foreign alliance whose backgrounds were often commercial who, for that reason, controlled :3 large monetary as sets. nese new agarian bourgeoisie considered their properties an inte egr al part of their overall L; _. . 1 investments an d triev to maize them as productive and pro— fitable as possible. One can conclude here that the deve- lopment of a de pen ndent agricul' tural bourgeoisie partly resulted as the Iranian agricultural economic sector became dependent on foreign-oriented production. The government agencies (i.e., the Cenjer for the -ttraction and Protection of Foreign Investments in Iran) started to advertise in order to attract the foreign .9 .. Richards, 1975:11). it the same time, the 408 government was ready to help both foreign and domestic 01’] O) ablish their enterprises. is Claw d‘ investors to es indicated, in ran, Government-sponsored . financial institutions have played the major role in introducing Q privatel -owned, enterpr neurial capitalism (1977:69J The government encouraged foreign capitalist involvement through the system of credit. The foreigners were awarded tariff protection, a ”five year tax holiday” and the :reedom to import whatever they desired. By the Fourth Development Plan in 1968 a new Agricultural Development Tund was created to invest heavily in ag_ibusiness. It received an initial fund of thirteen million dollars with the authority to borrow up to 3 200 million (Silsby, 1980: 51-52). Consequently,-agricultural fields for investment were opened up. Agri—ousinesses flowed into Iran because the rise of catitalist production relations in the country- , l :3 (D U "S (D O O {:5 {1; [..J Ll‘ ...; U 53 H) O ‘5 03 L3 (D H '_.l O Q: Q I.) H Q) U c 1 - I _I_ “ id capital I f 0 V ‘ . I‘ W l *1 I.) accumulation; that is, the profit rate in the n Iorld f is higher than at home. During 1970s, the governmen leased hundreds of thousands of hectares of productive H and to mutinational agribusiness. is FitzGerald reported,' it was easier for the government to rent land to foreigners than to help out its own small farrers (197fi:78). Private companies from Jhe United States and Great '9 4"? - ‘ f‘-/-v- ' ‘v- '5‘ V I-\ --L- a 3- J'- oi use world’s largeSt banks, iarm equiamene manuiacturers, 409 ‘l were ready to spend the hanized n s and for intensive mec :he owners of some of these corporation earnestly they could repeat th-eir California successes, enough water for irrigation, enough power plants aid enough insecticides and the petrochemical plants nee; l3r, success alnost guaranteed here....Anyone who annot make it n Ihuzistan has no busi we a being a farmer” (Iaraqi quoted Salmanzadeh, 1980:241). A comprehensive cont act was si,m ed between the government and the investors which spelled out the respon— sibilities ties. Under of both par government undertook to provide a to the investor (usually) Several to ific "ailable according a spec at the same time). The government construct the secondary canals for the delivery of . to each 100 hectare plOt each 1,000 hectare tract. electric Power (at the consumer's the investor from tax on any form other side, ce it was 8111 were not authorized, and access In addition, it also provi the ventures backed solely by for reign invest the contract, the certain amount of large tracts made time—table and not all also guaranteed to water and service roads to 'ded expense) and exempted machinery he used. On the to government policy encoura,ge joint Iranian—f0 oreign ventures. The investor had to agree to invest 80,000 Rials (3 1,145 per hectare during the first iive years of operation, and therefore 410 he was expected to keep the annual gross product value at about 60,000 Rials (3857) per hectare. The minimum area of a tract of land made available to an investor was 1,000 hectares and all land levelling was deemed to be the investor's responsibility, together with the construction of tar iary irrigation ca ls s, ditches, drainage and field roads. Fur thermore, the investor had to agree to employ one man for every ten hectares of land leased and after bfle iirst five years to reduce the number of his foreign staif to three per cent of his total personnel. In addition, he had to offer one apprenticeship for every 500 hectares leased (igro-industry and Settlement Department, 1973:7—9). Agribusiness units, both public and private, would be tablished on 500, 000 hectares of land (Aresvik, 1976:56). To assist in the capitalist trans-formation, the state provided renewable th rty-year leases to foreign and domes tic agribusiness compaines. The state was by far the bi gest investor in the agribusinesses. The initial conse- g quence was such that agribusinesses gained the li on's share of the most _ertile land in the country. According to the official statistics, there were 213 e.gr ribusinesses operating in 256,000 hectares land. Cut of these numbers, 7 units with 154,000 hectares were governe- nental; 202 units private with 40,000 hectares; and finally ‘ts governme ental ~nrivate I 'rms with 62, 000 h.ectares H) __| (lnosrovi, 1980:64). The greatest amount 0 concentrated in the hands of as C,ribusiness was located in Ehuzistan province. As a result of the D h R recommendation, a sugar cane plantation near Eaft Eappeh, north of Ahwaz in Lhuzistan, ned, and a subcontract made with the Brewer Companv o: iawaii to ma1 age it (Pichards,1975 :13). This agri—business included 10,800 hectares land within the boundary of the DI? (Ashraf, 1975:25). Another governmental agri—business in the Ehuzistan province was lhwaz Sugar Beet Factory with 9,127 hectares land located near nhwaz (Ibid.). In addition, the government had shares in the majority of foreign firms. In fact Khuzistan became the land of the giant agri- businesses, but they were operating in other provinces as well. Tirst Hashem haraqi Agro-Industry of Iran and America {of ten called the Iran-America lgribusniness) began operating in 1969 on 20,267 hectares, and its ori al major .share m holder was an emigrant Iranian, Hashem Naraqi, a naturalized American and one of the biggest almond gro Jere in California dis share was 51%.Other shareholders t Eational City Bank, hew Torn with 50%; lranians’ Bank, Tehran with 10%; and three individual stocld dolders with 9% shares (Richards, 1975:14). rie second gi ant agribusiness, Iran-California Agri- business Company, was founded in June 1970, as a partners chi betvnn the inerican- d cans-W0 ld Agricultural Develoo- meno with 302 share,9 and the agricultural Developm rent Fund of Iran (433:) with 15% shares. The other shareholders D were: 273;, 5%; I I. laleghani and Partners, 10%; Bank rinancial Corn. 20%; John Deere Crop., 10%; and Dow Chemical Corp. with 10% shares (Tichaids S 1975:14).This agribusiness had access to 10,536 hectares land (Salmanzadeh, 19802228). This agribusiness was initiallgr managed by 78 year old. George Wilson, who from 1951 to 1955 had headed the Ca ifornia Farm Bureau :edera tion (lbid., p. 240). The third agribusiness, Shell-Cotts Agribusiness of Iran, was established upon the recommendation of Lord Rothschild, a friend of the Shah and a member of the Shell board. The company brought in an international transport and commodity brokerage firm Hit chell Cotts Ltd. 4 to manage the new agribusiness ( 0f. ?_ichard, 1975:16). Ehell— Cotts Agribusiness of Iran, established on 18th Jcnuarv 1971, was initially a tria mlar oartner ship between lranian 1nvestorc (aD_i, 15u' aoo Bank Cmran 10 M, ihe ?oyal Dctch/ Thell group (70%) and the British 0 o n compaiy held 14,736 hectares of land. inalli, I should mention the International Agribusiness k J O :3 Q 93 {3 k: 0 H). l i ‘1 Q) [j vhich emerged on June 1975. 60 perc nt of the investment was of foreign origin and 40 per cent of domestic origi ‘. One of the foreign investors was the nawaiian hgronomic Company (with 15% shares) which acted as 413 —’f a major participant in establishing the Heft Tappeh sugar cane plan ation in the late fifties and early sixties. The Japanese Hitsui held 15 per cent of the shares. The other foreign investors were: Chase Manhattan Bank, 15%; and Diamond 3 Cattle (Roswell, few Mexico) 15%. The lrsnian p rtners were as follows: Bank Kelli ( 5% Ahwaz Sugar Beet Factory, 15%; lDrl, 15% and KWPA, 15% (3a almanzadeh, 1980:240; Richards, 1975:14). This agribusiness was allotted 16,680 hectares of land. is we can see, the Iranian government invested in all the above mentioned agribusinesses ex ept the Iran-American .1. one. The investment of the overnment was not limited to (79 h I..J Q) g"busninesses of th Khuzistan. Wherever the government (3' uilt a dam, ;rt invested in partnership with foreign O 1 investors. In Azarbayjan province, the Iranian Ministry of Agriculture and the Hawaiian :4.gronomics, Dunlop Ltd., and a Japanese firm were jointly creating th as country' s largest agribusiness unit in the Meghan steppe below the lras Dam. in area of 50,585 hectares was prepared for cultivation and meat industries (Bagley, 1976:34). is oil revenues rose, the government became more involved in large-scale farming investment. During the 1970s the government became heavily involved in a number of joint ventures with foreign firms. The Minis stry of agricul ture in conjun notion with two British consu ant firms, drew up a 20-year national development plan in 1975 designed to promoted large-scale iarming mostly r) A I based on agribusiness (Salmanzadeh, intention of the government to establish the dairy and meat 414 complexes in the major tribal livestock breeding areas-- ars, Kurdistan, Luristan, and Azerbayjan (Aresvik,1976:114). hj Projects like these are another indicator of the uneven development of capitalism in Iranian agriculture after the land reform. 16.3. Agribusinesses in Operation The agribusinesses tried to shape the Iranian agri— cultural system to meet the needs of the export sector rather than those of the internal market. Between 1969 and 1973 the government leased hundreds of thousands of hectares of productive land to mutinational agribusinesses across the country. During this time 62,219 hectares of the most fertile land of the Khuzistan was allotted to four giant agribusinesses. Table 16.1 indicates detailed information on these large-scale California—style componies. In this section I focus on these four agribusinesses since there is not much information available about other ones in the country. 0f the total 20,267 hectares allotted _\ to the Iran-America Agribusiness, 4,567 hectares were actually handed over, of which a quarter was levelled originally. However, by utilizing unlevelled land in the 1973-74 cropping year, the company had nearly 5,700 hectares under winter crops and 2,600 hectares under summer crops. _‘ The company also established several large citrus orchards covering a total area of 550 hectares. It was claimed hat by being the first agr business to be established in the [.1 415 mmmuommp .cmcswcmspwm ”wunzom 3R: 2&2 .52 .53 86.2 E 8a 98 Ba Sod 8m; EN: Q2 95.: 2 EB 33 .83 555 69.3 a s2 8 8: and m8; 086 N86 is 2 €S~ :69 :88: .53 3.2 2 at 3m 3 Sam 8;. some 82 02:. EB 2K9 .53 .53 Edam ..N 0? 8w Soto. mood zed $3: a8, .08 NH Bean 8335 .m: m: a: E an Era 588 895d mayor, 8:93 683. E32 68.88 83m .2805? laced. , 9.3 $005 LEE :39 3:: can“? Emmi; do handgun 3e: 53933.net: wgfli no dz .38 I’lllallll. tam 8.2a SCH 8 ho SH. ANN-H .HO .8 8657.3 in? Hana: Jame; are final cu»: do .28 8 Ease 8v 919:3. 1r? ESTZQM tun: 32: ES «.3 «533 a $45 is? £534.39 Ito): :1:qu 2‘43; 822% 03:; :35: HO x2950.“ ROWE 53:8 $2.: :2 Eat 3E3 as "a @958 23.3.6 5;: «5 59¢ luau: 538 @850 Sauna 3m: :38. 90 nsz :mumw~::¥.:a mmmmwcwmsawnm< Lows: ”_.op w_nm» 416 area, Ir n- -America Agribusiness acquired the best land, suitable for alfalfa and vegetables, particularly asparagous,' primarily for export purposes (Salmanzadeh, 1980:240). This company had the second highest investment among the agribusinesses of the region. It had the desire to use D‘ r5 ..A w igh proportion of machinery. As Rechards has indicated (1975:16), when all his fancy farm machinery arrived at the Persian Gulf port of Khorramshahr, haraqi paraded it to Dez in order to dramatize the takeover of agr ic culture y I”) large— —scale enter p ise. Earaqi’s aim was to rea. pro its through the export of asparagous and other produce sought abroad. As one reporter noted: From here yearly asparagus will be flown to “orthern Eurpoe before an asparagus tip breaks ground elsewhere; here tomatoes, sugar cane, alfalfa (for Japan) (United States, Department of Agriculture, 1978). The company began exporting asparagus by air to Europe in 1971 (Bagley, 1976:35). In addition, fresh fruit and vegetables were shiped to oil rich Kuwait, Bahrayn, Abu Dhabi and Dubai (Freivalds, 1972:190). The total number of laborers employed by the company was nearly 1,000 of which only one fifth were permanent staff. This company relied heavily upon seasonal cheap laborers. It was a real example of capital-intensive fa; ming, since on an average it had one worker per 10 hectares of cultivation. The total land allotted to the Iran-California Agri- business was 10,5561 qec tares, of which nearly half had been 417 leased by January 1974 and approx1 ma ly 3, 800 hect ares were levelled by harsh 1974. The company had nearly 3,700 hectares under winter crops and 840 hectares under summer crops. The company was growing a wide variety of crops. An interesting feature of land use by this company was the C .1. L: sub-lease of 100 hectares of its land to Isfahani migrar peasant workers. Part of this company's labor requirement was drawn from the previous nasaq—holding local peasants who were paid hourly. The total number of laborers employed by the company was nearly 400, of which nearly half were seaonal laborers. By sub—leasing land to his laborers,the company reduced the cost of the reproduction of labor force. Iran—California planned to grow wheat, maize, fodder crops, sugar beet, vegetables and cotton, to breed livestock, and to build a vegetable processing and packin ng plant a \. cold storage plant and a cotton ginnery (Bagley,1979:33). The company was able to produce most of the products it planned to gr ow, but it did not build any processing plants .1. e farming level. C—enerally speaking, the c+ q A .- a 5.1. and remaine b — company was not as success as the iran-America Company in exporting material to other countries. its main produce was for domestic markets. 14,736 hectares. 3y harch 1974, about 4, leased and 3,800 hectares levelled. In the 1973-74 cropping year, the company had 1,565 hect res under winter crops and »i hectares under summer crops. The com anv invested 418 mainly in oil- seed cultivation and stockbreeding. Cf 2,891 hectares of summer crops, 1,940 hectares were cotton (Bagley, 1976:34). The Shell-Cotts had opted for a capita l-intens ”v approach (Richards,1975:17). However, in prOportion a to amount of land released to it, Shellécotts employed a higher ratio of permanent laborers than any of the compaines. It was expected the compani would employ 1,500 iranian and would reduced the proportion of foreign ‘emploxees to one per cent by 1976 (Eagley, 1976:34). Out of its total land allocation of 16,680 hectares, nternational Agribusiness of Iran had received 4,240 hectares by January 1974, of which 1,250 hectares were levelled. The company experimented with the introduction of sturdy beef cattle breeds for intensive meat production. As we can see from the table 16.1, the company had the highest amount of capital compared to the other three companies. It was a very capital-intensive company. The 1 company had the desire to import a massive number of the o C I._J H, rom the United States. It was ,part of the govern- .g ments' plan to ask the company for a comprehensive deve lop- ment of meat production. Concurrent with the establishment of the agribusi me see, plans were drawn up to replace illa ages involvec i; the agribusiness scheme with new resettlement centers or shahraks ('small-town'). The number of villages incruded in .D 4.7 ,q n_- ._ . . _.; these iour agriouSihesses 18 g_ vs {'5 ‘ J {.3 Cl- Cu O I } ..J (D ._A O\ . of 13 shahraks were planned to replace the 100 villages involved in hhuzistan (3al_anza 53 the ethnic c Q) 0 :7 0Q H O S D' Q. I- O l 3 d‘ D 1‘5 (D (D U) :3 m4 "S fl) '5? U) I...) b’ d- L) (D {5 (D 2?. resettlement centers of has Irri province. As we can see, some of these centers even included four ethnic groups (i.e., Zhusrou shahrak . The typical residential area of each shahrak contained eries of rows of four-housing units, with a maximum h fa w 0‘) capacity of 500 units. Each of these units was designed for occupation by one household and consisted of two'main’ rooms (6XA and 2X3 square metres) and a 'lot of approximately I" I .J 700 square metres of land. Eacl snahrak had a population as a town. 0n the other htnd, no faim land was attached to any of these centres so they could nOt be corSidered as villages. Furthermore, no admiristrative prov;s;oi was made for the administration of shahraks,and no ediustments were a I v 1 made Since they came into existence in 1;72. This led t ‘9" h . 1r- fl - - . ‘. 1, J—‘ . A 3,}- ‘ . 1" ‘ fl 7“,“ CI. 1.513;. CI 883‘! 1065 , fl OT 3135 bflere c2. -‘.€oal\;’l‘d La or UZGQTOI' . Thus , .«1 ~-'1 '. .-- .:.. 1 .0 ‘.I_ .2. :3: G .L. ,- - - .\ eacn agricuSiness aoponted a member oi le stall asotemporar, - “-0 - ~ n“. * A , - _' y'fl- - no . 2“" ’unoriiCiai‘ snahrak supervisor (ca mansaten, 15o0:243). 420 £1. (1) £31 ‘0 .._\ \ O 03 rt) 0 m JLX \JJ V M {D D D. C f' :3 (D A ‘l 3 Table 16.2: Ethnic Background of Villages included in the New Resettlement Center of DIP Mane of VLLlages' Included Ethnic Bad