.1 IA g... . "‘ In a m ! f . ‘ ! “gag. ‘ .1 ""‘-h . . a v. \ ‘ — U ~' . ‘ .I w- . .u‘ ABSTRACT MANUFACTURING PROGRESS FUNCTIONS BY Dayr Ramos Americo dos Reis The Manufacturing Progress Function (MPF) may be gener ally defined as the relationship in which the labor input per unit used in the manufacture of a product tends to de- cline by a constant percentage as the cumulative quantity produced is doubled. Where this relationship is present, it may be represented by a straight line in a double logarithmic scale. The prime objective of this study is to contribute a general symbolic-analytic model of the manufacturing progress phenomenon . Once the general model is established, an equally important objective is to respond to the need for a coherent systematic approach to be used in predicting the develop- ments of the adaptation process in industrial concerns of almost any kind . The work is broadly divided into four major parts. Chapter II contains a comprehensive review of the historical development of the Manufacturing Progress Function and a Summary of the more important contributions to the progress .ffl" ‘- ...E-- ‘- p IA " p ...\v . r-vv. 4 " ’IA fin. uh. .~_ II U L‘Y‘>~ ‘ . .1‘ ~ .. ~o...‘ -.'.' v .- :v \v ”I.“ .’ w “v” '1 .n H “n it. ~' ‘5 . \ ~ ‘9‘ Dayr Ramos Americo dos Reis curve literature that are relevant to this dissertation. The field of progress functions lacks notation unifor mity, precise definition of the variables and functional relationships involved, and formal mathematical proofs of several assumed results. A coherent mathematical exposition can be the basis for the derivation of new important results. Towards this end an original theoretical systematization is offered in Chapter III. Chapter IV represents a continuation of the mathematical exposition initiated in Chapter III. Two related topics of practical relevance are approached: the integration of progress functions and the debatable problem of their aggregation. Original approximations are proposed for both problems. A general symbolic-analytic model of the manufacturing progress phenomenon is offered in Chapter V. In Chapter VI the manufacturing progress model presented in Chapter V is tested with real data from nine manufacturers representing five different industries. A hundred and fifty-nine separate cases of product and process startups that occurred in four different countries and nine distinct plants are analyzed. In addition, aggregate data was obtained for whole industries in one country, yielding nine more startups. The descriptive efficiency of the proposed model is generally supported by the results of regression analysis of the startups and startup parameters obtained from the partig iPating industrial firms. r" .u... . ...,o 0‘." n..‘. r ”a: ..., Dayr Ramos Americo dos Reis The findings of this research and previous findings by two other authors constitute adequate evidence to suggest that the model can be developed into an effective means of predicting the mathematical slope (parameter b) of a new startup. The author believes that the parameter model amproach presented in Chapter V has proved to be superior to (fiber existing methods for estimating the parameters of a rmw startup. The dissertation is concluded (Chapter VII) with a (fiscussion of the industrial implications of the findings reported in Chapter VI. The importance of recognizing and {medicting the manufacturing progress phenomenon is related u>several decision-making functions that are encountered in mIindustrial setting as well as in economic planning at the Imtional level. An overall design of a computerized bhnufacturing Progress Function (MPF) System is suggested. MANUFACTURING PROGRESS FUNCTIONS By Dayr Ramos Americo dos Reis A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Management 1977 © Copyright by DAYR RAMOS AMERICO DOS REIS 1977 TO MY FATHER JULIO AMERICO DOS REIS, Aer.Eng. A PIONEER OF THE BRAZILIAN AIRFRAME INDUSTRY (1910-1977) IN MEMORIAM ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The author wishes to express appreciation for the guid- ance and encouragement provided by Dr. Richard F. Gonzalez, as advisor throughout the thesis. The time and assistance of Dr. Stanley E. Bryan, Dr. Dole A. Anderson and Dr. Phillip L. Carter have also been of great value. The author is also indebted to a large number of indi- viduals in industry for their helpful cooperation. These individuals, who must unfortunately remain anonymous,provided the essential data for the dissertation. I am grateful to Mrs. Doris Singer who so patiently assisted in revising the manuscript. Without my wife, Maria de Fatima, who assisted me with editing and typing and was a source of constant inspiration, this work might never have been completed. DAYR R.A. DOS REIS February, 1977 iii iv TABLE OF CONTENTS page LIST OF TABLES ........................................ xi LIST OF FIGURES ....................................... xvi CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION: THE PERCEPTION OF THE PROBLEMATIC SITUATION ............................................. l Adaptation to Innovation and Transformation ........... 2 ‘Manufacturing Progress Function Defined ............... 5 Scope ................................................. 6 GENERAL AND SPECIFIC OBJECTIVES OF THE STUDY .......... 8 A Note on Models ...................................... 8 General Statement of Objectives ....................... 9 CHAPTER II THE EXISTING BODY OF KNOWLEDGE ........................ 11 THE WRIGHT MODEL ...................................... 11 THE FORTIES ........................................... 14 The Crawford Model .................................... 15 Bureau of Labor Statistics Studies .................... 17 Airframe Companies Publications ....................... 19 Progress Curves in Great Britain and France ........... 28 Other Contributions ................................... 31 TABLE OF CONTENTS (cont'd) page THE FIFTIES ........................................... 33 Extensions of the Concept Outside the Airframe Industry .............................................. 34 Airframe Companies Publications ....................... 46 Studies Financed by the Air Force ..................... 47 Other Contributions ................................... 51 THE SIXTIES AND SEVENTIES ............................. 52 Extension to Machine-Intensive Manufacture ............ 52 Contributions by IBM Personnel ........................ 55 Other Contributions ................................... 59 SUMMARY ............................................... 65 Review of Main Hypotheses ............................. 67 CHAPTER III MANUFACTURING PROGRESS FUNCTIONS: A MATHEMATICAL EXPOSITION ............................................ 69 FOUR TYPES OF PROGRESS FUNCTIONS ...................... 70 Type 1: The Unit Progress Function .................... 70 Type 2: The Cumulative Average Progress Function ...... 73 Type 3: The Cumulative Total Progress Function ........ 74 Type 4: The Lot Average Progress Function ............. 75 FUNDAMENTAL PROBLEMS .................................. 78 Statement of Fundamental Problems ..................... 78 Solution of Problem I ................................. 79 Solution of Problem II ................................ 82 V TABLE OF CONTENTS (cont'd) Solution of Problem III ............................... pig? Solution of Problem IV ................................ 86 PARAMETER CALCULATION ................................. 90 Statement of Problem Al ............................... 91 Solution of Problem A1 ................................ 91 Statement of Problem A2 ............................... 92 Solution of Problem A2 ................................ 92 Statement of Problem A3 ............................... 92 Solution of Problem A3 ................................ 93 Statement of Problem A4 ............................... 93 Solution of Problem A4 ................................ 93 Statement of Problem B1 ............................... 94 Solution of Problem B1 ................................ 94 Statement of Problem B2 ............................... 95 Solution of Problem BZ ................................ 96 Statement of Problem B3 ............................... 97 Solution of Problem BB ................................ 97 Statement of Problem B4 ............................... 100 Solution of Problem B4 ................................ 100 SUMMARY ............................................... 103 CHAPTER IV QUADRATURE AND SUMMATION OF PROGRESS FUNCTIONS ........ 104 QUADRATURE OF PROGRESS FUNCTIONS ...................... 104 Cumulative Total Hours Calculation .................... 104 vi TABLE OF CONTENTS (cont'd) Manufacturing Progress Function Hours Calculation ..... USE? Accuracy of the Proposed Formulas ..................... 113 THE AGGREGATION PROBLEM ............................... 113 Statement of the Problem .............................. 116 Solution of the Aggregation Problem ................... 117 Accuracy of the Proposed Aggregation Method ........... 126 Accuracy in the Quadrature of Approximate Aggregate Functions ............................................. 133 CHAPTER V A MODEL OF THE PROGRESS PHENOMENON IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES ............................................ 136 A CONCEPT OF MANUFACTURING PROGRESS ................... 136 Factors in Manufacturing Progres ...................... 137 Hypotheses About the Progress Phenomenon - A Reexamination ....................................... 141 MANUFACTURING PROGRESS - - A MODEL .................... 145 The Traditional Model: Some Qualifications ............ 146 Estimating the Ultimate Point (xu, yu) ................ 147 Estimating Parameter b ............................... 149 A Symbolic-Analytic Model of the Manufacturing Progress Phenomenon ............................................. 149 GENERAL METHODOLOGY OF THE EMPIRICAL RESEARCH .......... 151 Criteria in Sample Selection .................. ' ......... 151 The Sample ............................................. 152 vii TABLE OF CONTENTS (cont'd) Measuring the Progress Phenomenon ..................... CHAPTER VI EMPIRICAL FINDINGS .................................... STARTUP ANALYSIS IN THE MANUFACTURING OF ELECTRONIC DATA PROCESSING SYSTEMS AND COMPONENTS ................ Characteristics of the Products and Manufacturing Processes Studied ..................................... Startup Measurement and Data .......................... Startup Analysis ...................................... Parameter Analysis .................................... STARTUP ANALYSIS IN THE MANUFACTURING OF BINDERY 'MACHINES AND PRINTING PRESSES ......................... Characteristics of the Products and Manufacturing Processes Studied ..................................... Startup Measurement and Data .......................... Startup Analysis ...................................... Parameter Analysis .................................... STARTUP ANALYSIS IN SHIPBUILDING ...................... Characteristics of the Product and Manufacturing Processes Studied ..................................... Startup Measurement and Data .......................... Startup Analysis ...................................... Parameter Analysis .................................... viii 158 158 158 163 165 167 178 178 178 180 180 188 188 189 191 192 TABLE OF CONTENTS (Cont'd) STARTUP ANALYSIS IN THE MANUFACTURING OF OIL page DRILLING AND PRODUCTION EQUIPMENT ..................... 194 Characteristics of the Products and Manufacturing Processes Studied ..................................... 194 Startup Measurement and Data .......................... 195 Startup Analysis ...................................... 196 Parameter Analysis .................................... 196 STARTUP ANALYSIS IN THE AIRFRAME INDUSTRY ............. 198 Characteristics of the Products and Manufacturing Processes Studied ..................................... 198 Startup Measurement and Data .......................... 199 Startup Analysis ...................................... 201 Parameter Analysis .................................... 201 STARTUP ANALYSIS IN THE MECHANICAL AND ELECTRICAL INDUSTRY .............................................. 204 The Product Groups Studied ............................ 204 Startup Measurement and Data .......................... 206 Startup Analysis ...................................... 207 Parameter Analysis .................................... 207 SUMMARY ............................................... 209 CHAPTER VII IMPLICATIONS OF THE FINDINGS .......................... 212 IMPLICATIONS AT FIRM LEVEL ............................ 212 Problem Statement ..................................... 214 ix TABLE OF CONTENTS (cont'd) page Solution .............................................. 216 MULTINATIONALS AND THE COST OF LEARNING ............... 237 IMPLICATIONS AT NATIONAL LEVEL ........................ 239 Determining the Magnitude of Contracts ................ 240 A COMPUTERIZEDMPF SYSTEM ............................. 242 CHAPTER VIII SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS ............................... 248 APPENDICES APPENDIX A: MATHEMATICAL PROOFS ....................... 256 APPENDIX B: EQUATION OF THE ASYMPTOTE TO THE CURVE REPRESENTING THE LOGARITHM OF THE UNIT PROGRESS FUNCTION .............................................. 258 APPENDIX C: PARAMETER FORMULAS DERIVATION ............. 262 APPENDIX D: STABILITY OF COEFFICIENTS :_n_ AND E OF THE PARAMETER MODEL ................................ 265 APPENDIX E: A CODE FOR CALCULATING a x29 x’b WITH AN HP-25 SCIENTIFIC PROGRAMMABLE POCKE]T CALCULATOR. . .. 292 APPENDIX F: DATA TABLES (CHAPTER VI) .................. 291: APPENDIX G: REGRESSION ANALYSIS OF LOG- TRANSFORMED DATA - - A FORTRAN IV PROGRAM ............. 317 BIBLIOGRAPHICAL NOTES ................................. 319 BIBLIOGRAPHY .......................................... 339 X R: v'q fly: to. xi LIST OF TABLES Table page 2.1 PARAMETERS OF THE PROGRES CURVE ................. 22 2.2. INFLUENCE OF THE NEWNESS OF MODELS AND FACILITIES ON THE RELATIVE POSITION OF PROGRESS CURVES ................................. 25 4.1 EXACT AND APPROXIMATE CUMULATIVE TOTAL HOURS; a=100, b=0.152003 (90% curve) ............ 114 4.2 EXACT AND APPROXIMATE AGGREGATE PROGRESS FUNCTION - INTERVAL [:1, 1000:] ................. 127 4.3 EXACT AND APPROXIMATE AGGREGATE PROGRESS FUNCTION - INTERVAL [:1, 20:] ................... 131 6.1 STARTUPS ANALYZED IN FIRMS A, B AND C ........... 161 6.2 STARTUPS ANALYZED IN FIRMS D AND E .............. 162 6.3 FINAL ASSEMBLY OF THE CPU OF A THIRD GENERATION COMPUTER (FIRM A) .................... 294 6.4 MANUFACTURING OF CARD PUNCH X (FIRM A) .......... 294 6.5 ASSEMBLY OF MAJOR UNITS OF CARD PUNCH Y (FIRM A) ................................ 295 6-6. FINAL ASSEMBLY 6: TESTING OF CARD PUNCH X (FIRM B) ................................ 295 6.7 FINAL ASSEMBLY OF CARD PUNCH Y (FIRM C) ......... 295 6.8. ASSEMBLY OF 2nd GENERATION COMPUTER ' UNITS (FIRM D, PROGRAM .4; 1) ..................... 296 .Ann u \x- -: .out‘.. ‘4 ('1 n I. 'I t‘ p Table 6.9 6. O‘O‘O‘ 10 .11 .12 .13 .14 .15 .16 .17 .18 .19 .20 .21 .22 .23 .24 LIST OF TABLES (cont'd) ASSEMBLY OF SMALL COMPUTER COMPONENTS (FIRM D, PROGRAM # 2) ........................... ASSEMBLY OF COMPUTER COMPONENTS AND DATA STORAGE UNITS (FIRM E) .......................... MPF REGRESSION RESULTS .......................... FIRM A PARAMETERS 3 AND B ....................... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM A, CPU OF A 3rd.GENERATION COMPUTER) ...... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM A, CARD PUNCH X) .......................... FIRM D PARAMETERS g.AND g ....................... FIRM E PARAMETERS a AND E ....................... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM D) ..... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM E) ..... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM D, STARTUPS D12, D1, D4 AND D3 EXCLUDED).. PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM D, STARRED STARTUPS IN TABLE 6.15 EXCLUDED) ........ PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM E, STARTUPS E11 AND E10 EXCLUDED) .................. PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM E, STARRED STARTUPS IN TABLE 6.15 EXCLUDED) ........ STARTUPS ANALYZED IN FIRM F (U.S.) .............. MANUFACTURING OF BINDING MACHINES ' AND PRINTING PRESSES, FIRM F (U.S) .............. xii 297 298 299 168 169 169 172 173 174 174 175 176 177 177 179 303 Table 625 680 LIST OF TABLES (cont'd) FIRM F PARAMETERS _c_: AND B ...................... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F). . .. PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F, STARTUP F4 EXCLUDED) .................. PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F, STARTUPS F4 AND F5 EXCLUDED) .......... PARAMETERS £1 AND t_> (FIRM F,BINDING MACHINES). . . . PARAMETERS a AND E (FIRM F,PRINTING PRESSES).... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F, BINDING MACHINES) ..................... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F,PRINTING PRESSES) ...................... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F, BINDING MACHINES, F4 AND F5 EXCLUDED) .................................. PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F, BINDING MACHINES; F4, F5 AND F2 EXCLUDED) ...... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F, PRINTING PRESSES, F28 EXCLUDED) ................ PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM F, PRINTING PRESSES; F28, F21 AND F22 EXCLUDED).... STARTUPS ANALYZED IN FIRM G (BRAZIL) ........... SHIPBUILDING, FIRM G (BRAZIL) .................. FIRM G PARAMETERS a AND E ...................... xiii page 181 183 183 183 308 309 185 185 185 186 187 187 190 310 193 “H“: - on. ”I“ 0" ‘ ~‘ I - 1 P A . - ' u. - . 1 I AI . u I ." .,~ I A . n I ,3 "s l .- \ Table 6. O‘GO‘O‘O‘ 40 .41 .42 .43 .44 .45 .46 .47 .48 .49 .50 .51 .52 .53 LIST OF TABLES (cont'd) PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM A, FERRY-BOAT OF 1250 DWT) ......................... STARTUPS ANALYZED IN FIRM H (BRAZIL) ............ OIL DRILLING TOOLS & EQUIPMENT, FIRM H (BRAZIL) ................................ FIRM H PARAMETERS adAND b ...................... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM H, OIL DRILLING AND PRODUCTION EQUIPMENT) ......... STARTUPS ANALYZED IN FIRM I (BRAZIL) ........... AIRFRAME INDUSTRY, FIRM I (BRAZIL) ............. PARAMETERS a AND E (FIRM I, SPARE PARTS) ....... FIRM I PARAMETERS _a AND 13 (PRODUCTS) ........... PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM I, PRODUCTS, STARTUPS II THROUGH I4) .............. PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (FIRM I, SPARE PARTS, STARTUPS I5 THROUGH I69) .......... MECHANICAL AND ELECTRICAL INDUSTRY (BRAZIL: 1960-1964) ............................ INDUSTRY J PARAMETERS _a AND 13 .................. PARAMETER MODEL REGRESSION RESULTS (INDUSTRY J, STARTUPS J1 THROUGH J9) ........... MANUFACTURING PROGRESS FUNCTION AND COST DATA ...................................... PRODUCTION SCHEDULE (PRODUCT P) ................ ULTIMATE HOURS AND UNITS (PRODUCT P) ........... xiv page 194 195 311 197 197 200 200 312 202 202 203 316 208 209 214 215 217 . i "'7 ' 'A‘M ”.1. ' u u ‘05; I ”Hy: .. , ._ - C. 4 u... . H.- ‘ 'a. . ._. I.“ 1 IO. .. -p- : Oil "- ._. '- V I I , .- I “h In I: .H 'r Y ‘ l A “9 .- H. . u . -. ~h‘ ’I I \ . 1. ‘ Y ‘ 1 I 7 c- i O . 'g ! ~'. . 1 1|- : 1.. I . '> R ‘ . . .. k v. A J 1 Table UUUU LIST OF TABLES (cont'd) '24. PARAMETER a VALUES CALCULATED page ACCORDING TO FORMULA (5.6) ...................... 218 5 MPF HOURS AND COST CALCULATION (EXACT METHOD) ..220 6 MPF HOURS AND COST CALCULATION (APPROXIMATE METHOD) ............................ 221 7 TOTAL LABOR HOURS FOR PRODUCT P (EXACT METHOD) .................................. 223 8 LABOR AND SPACE REQUIREMENTS (MECH. ASSY., EXACT METHOD) ..................... 226 9 LABOR AND SPACE REQUIREMENTS ELECT. ASSY , EXACT METHOD) ..................... 227 .10 LABOR AND SPACE REQUIREMENTS (TESTING, EXACT METHOD) ......................... 228 .11 LABOR AND SPACE REQUIREMENTS (FINAL ASSY. AND TESTING, EXACT METHOD) ...................... 231 .12 LABOR AND SPACE REQUIREMENTS (TESTING, APPROXIMATE METHOD) ................... 233 .13 AGGREGATE LABOR AND SPACE REQUIREMENTS (FINAL ASSY. AND TESTING, AGGREGATE PROGRESS FUNCTION METHOD) ....................... 236 1. SAMPLE 1, FIRM D ................................ 268 2 SAMPLE 2, FIRM D ................................ 268 3 SAMPLE 1, FIRM F ................................ 278 4- SAMPLE 2, FIRM F ................................ 279 XV flglf \— ‘1” v.-. Inq— soi- LIST OF TABLES (cont'd) Table ‘page 115 SAMPLE 1 (SIMULATES PAST DATA) ................... 286 116 SAMPLE 2 (SIMULATES NEW STARTUPS) ................ 286 117 PREDICTED PARAMETER b VALUES ..................... 291 118 PREDICTED PARAMETER a VALUES ..................... 291 xvi . .~.'. «a. ‘- ’Y‘ xvii LIST OF FIGURES Figure page PLOTTING THE PROGRESS LINE FOR A GIVEN CATEGORY ............................... 44 2 PROGRESS ON ARITHMETIC GRAPH ................... 46 3 PROGRESS LINE FOR A CATALYTIC CRACKING UNIT. . . . 62 4 PROGRESS CURVE ULTIMATE POINT (xu, yu) AND MANUFACTURING PROGRESS FUNCTION HOURS .......... 105 5 EXACT AND APPROXIMATE CUMULATIVE TOTAL HOURS vs. CUMULATIVE PRODUCTION a = 100, b = 0.152003 (90:, curve) ............. 115 6 EXACT AND APPROXIMATE AGGREGATE PROGRESS FUNCTION - - INTERVAL [1, 1009] 129 '7 EXACT AND APPROXIMATE AGGREGATE PROGRESS FUNCTION - - INTERVAL [1, 20:] 132 8 VISUAL TABLE OF CONTENTS OF THE PACKAGE DESCRIBING THE MPF SYSTEM ...................... 243 9 OVERVIEW DIAGRAM NUMBERED 1.0 OF THE MPF SYSTEM (THE HIGHEST-LEVEL DIAGRAM) ..... 244 10 OVERVIEW DIAGRAM NUMBERED 2.0 OF THE MPF SYSTEM ................................. 245 11 OVERVIEW DIAGRAM NUMBERED 3.0 OF THE MPF SYSTEM ................................. 246 1.1; . U nan!- .. FY":- .. .1- A'- v: LIST OF FIGURES (cont'd) 5 Figure page 12 OVERVIEW DIAGRAM NUMBERED 4.0 OF THE MPF SYSTEM .............................. 247 xviii an A"' p” SHJSV.‘ Q 1 V?!‘ '15 D _. w.» 6.6., ....'._ : ‘ls-n. ‘. 'DI.- H ‘ , ~ ‘ ‘ A... «v». ., ' In “A'~ R ' A ..., “Vic‘s. . ' I ‘4... b l ..,:'.-'l‘: u: my. 5 ‘5 ‘b , V - : . u‘ .1“ ‘u “’19:. ¢,. . . O I V .\ 4 F ‘ §G . - P. ‘I,‘A"‘ 3w ~ I .‘H‘ ‘ '\ I- 5‘ 01 n .. I. P . n . I a}. ‘« CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION: THE PERCEPTION OF THE PROBLEMATIC SITUATION Presumably, the process of economic progress involves three levels of activity: invention, innovation and transfog mation. Invention is a new idea, the discovery of relation ships not before perceived. Innovation is the pioneering application of an invention. Transformation constitutes the substitution of existing processes and outputs by those which innovation has already shown to be superior or preferable. The end result of transformation is economic progress. It is perhaps a platitude to say that the industrial environment in the United States and abroad - including some modern less developed countries - has been characterized by an ever increasing rate of technological innovation and tranSfOrmation. Some degree of innovation and transformation is shared by virtually all manufacturing industries and their c . Omponent enterprises . Given that rapid innovation and transformation proces§_ es have become the environment as well as the internal life of a large number of industries - here and abroad - it is appropriate and opportune to investigate the possible influ- ence Of those processes upon the manufacturing activities of the aft.eczted firms and their consequences in terms of deCis ion ~making . u ...N“ .‘ .-~\ in. P wuus - ' .1. 2 Adaptation to Innovation and Transformation Innovation or transformation imply change, and change gmMmates the need for adaptation. In the implementation of arww product, the following represent general decision- mfldng areas in which the adaptation phenomenon might have mabe taken into account: Long-range forecasting and planning for capacities and locations. Selection of equipment and processes . Production design Job design and work measurement . Location of the system Facility layout Short-range forecasting Inventory control Aggregate planning and scheduling Scheduling and production control MMintenance Quality control Labor and cost control SuChalist indicates that the adaptation phenomenon D .ervades the whole activity of the production system. It 8 18° SUSgests the wide variety of talents that might be i . nvolved in resolving the problems generated by system adap- tation to change. a W! A S3300: - ie'.'e‘.00:en Titian prc fixture. in re 22:10:; can I y ' "": firm-"M .. .... 4.Uuu\. . I ....... , A . .C v'r a_ -v~.. bib u. .‘ A 1 . ~=- .1» .101: \r In "3":‘5, " u, a . ~n~v~b.‘.. his 'u . I v.2.‘3y'o a“b““» 1 .‘_.h. H)" “a Es.‘DOr I. F. 3 Productivity, System Adaptation and Decision-Making. The development and implementation of new products or new production processes can alter the means and methods of manu facture. In responding to these changes the production orga- nization can experience a period of adaptation. The efforts Of the production system give rise to notable increases in manufacturing productivity. In fact, it is generally known that the hours required to produce a new product decrease as cumulative production increases. Several studies in many different manufacturing areas and other situations support this assertion.1 The occurrence of this adaptation phenomenon in manu- facturing is rarely a consequence of direct-labor learning Of a manual task. The phenomenon usually results from an in- tegrated adaptation effort on the part of direct-labor, indi rect-labor and technical personnel. It relies primarily on Cognitive rather than manual learning. Managers, engineers, supe1""1-SOrs, machine operators, maintenance men, quality control personnel, purchasing personnel and other indirect- labor employees can all make important contributions toward 1 . o g o ncreaSIng the effICIency of a manufacturing process. This type of manufacturing progress phenomenon may have a Significant effect on many decision-making activities in a firm- Practically every manufacturing concern has to forecast labor time and cost per unit of new products in order to set S O elllng Prices, plan delivery schedules, estimate capital . ...-- :n 'W‘qc p I --Dv on M‘V h 7" “1".”‘31 I y. In... - 4,,\ LT‘ 4 labor and space needs, and the like. Large, sustained incre- mmn$ in productivity can influence a variety of planning muicontrol functions. N.Baloff suggests the following panflal list of decision-making areas that can be influenced by changes in productivity: "1. Price-setting. The level of productivity affects the direct manufacturing costs and, in many cases, the allocation of overhead costs. Delivery commitments. Delivery commitments cannot be made reliably unless the rate of product output can be correctly anticipated. Production scheduling. The rate of output of a "bottleneck" can materially affect the schedulingcflf other processes in a sequential manufacturing opera tion. Purchasing and raw material inventory. These ac- tivities must be synchronized with the productiv- ity of the production processes. Manpower requirements. Akin to the scheduling ‘problem, the total labor requirements in sequential manufacturing operations may depend on the rate of output of a new bottleneck process. 'Work standards. The determination of work stan- dards and wage incentives is both hazardous and Y7 Ayn-y. :10!qu ...:.: c ' ‘ "1 0. “"w tun . 2"? N‘Afi,‘ H . “H mm... . ....~ (We " ‘" ‘vu _ I ....:‘~ ‘ “N‘”: 6.1.1 “A. C . 5 difficult under conditions of changing productivity. 7. Cost accounting, budgeting, and cost control. These control procedures are sensitive to changing productivity, as well as being motivationally sensitive - a volatile combination." However, before considering the above list, the initial decision of whether or not to implement the new product, the major change or the new process must be made. In order to do this, one must count upon a valid and reliable tool for pre- dicting the pattern and the magnitude of the adaptation Phenomenon. Moreover, unless such productivity changes can be Predicted at the beginning of a manufacturing startup, an appreciable degree of costly uncertainty can result. Manufacturing progress functions (MPFs) have been docu mented for years in the literature as a means of describing and sometimes predicting the pattern and the magnitude of the adaptation phenomenon . MannfaCturing Progress Function Defined The manufacturing progress function (MPF) has been used in the literature to describe several different proposed relationships between the labor input involved in the opera- tions required to manufacture a product and the volume of plT’duetion. For the purpose of this dissertation the MPF can b _ e generally defined as the relationship in which the labor *" ”er U)"; ”Iv ! o ‘ ' A In: :11‘.e\l .‘l d" 4 . "II . u... .1 a: on. .,,_ ' a." .:’1' “J‘ “.1 ‘ . o ‘ Pat \‘-‘ a 1 “I .‘- ‘V . “.3“. ht.‘ a". ‘ " 'f’tn ‘6‘... N 1“ :-»...q“ K.‘:\'. in ., 9' E ." , . n 5‘ 5.“ s I. ‘\ . ‘O A‘{ . ‘3 in, \~_“ : . h \‘1, “on u ., .- HA I b.‘ ‘ -.‘ . K“: ; § ‘6. 2'3- '3“: V '«. ‘ v ""e O h ‘: J“ a k. 6 input per unit used in the manufacture of a product tends to decline by a constant percentage as the cumulative quantity produced is doubled. Where this relationship is present, it may be represented by a straight line in a double logarithmic scale. Chapter III is aimed at a complete clarification of this subject . Scope The following observations made by the author since 1959 have served the purpose of setting the scope for this dissertation . Universalization. The need for making the progress curve model more generally applicable in labor-intensive 3 manufacture has been stressed for years in the literature. To date, however, its importance has been mainly recognized by the aerospace industry apart some few extensions of the model to other labor and machine-intensive production SYStems . Form of the Model. The adequate form of the manu- facturing progress function model has also been discussed for Years. In the following work empirical support has been found for some of the forms proposed in the literature.5 The moSt POPUIar are the cumulative-average curve and the unit Cturve. Parameters Estimation. The estimation of the paramg te ' rs of the progress function for different products and ”(A .... u. . 7 processes has been of significant concern, although few authors have tried the empirical approach. It must be undeg stood that without a valid and reliable method for estimating the parameters of the manufacturing progress function before the inception of the production process, its usefulness as a predicting tool can be virtually dismissed. When Does Learning End? The occurrence and predict- flfility of steady-state plateaux in the curve have also been flMasubject of much argument and little empirical research effort.7 Comparative Studies. Comparative studies of produc- thfity values across facilities located in different coun- tnies are missing in the literature of the progress curve. Such an approach might provide thoughtful insights in theo- rizing about the adaptation phenomenon. Better Theoretical Systematization. The field of prOgress functions lacks notation uniformity, precise defini tion 055 the variables and relationships involved, and proofs of s"Wei-"a1 results assumed. A coherent mathematical exposi- tion can be the basis for the derivation of new theoretical results, RT'H‘ .. vh- ri'fl 1‘ 1L}: \u‘l . . " v..._."' . ‘ I “"vuo'us .. l "I P I- u ._. . :f :25 re‘ I u fi’A a VA:- .. C p‘ b... ‘55. n I .. F, a g 4....“ og‘l . ., _. ~..,'~ ' 'Jv ‘ L ‘0 .‘Fd'hlv' D.‘¥v1 ‘ ‘. (I) '0 8 GENERAL AND SPECIFIC OBJECTIVES OF THE STUDY A Note on Models Models are taken to be analogues of existing or con- ceivable systems, resembling their referent systems in form but not necessarily in content.8 They exhibit structural re- lationships among elements found in the referent system. At the same time they are abstractions, omitting some aspects Of the referent systems and duplicating only those that are of interest for the purposes at hand. A distinction can be drawn between representation and explanation and hence between models and theory. Models need 9111? represent the referent system; explanation is the role 0f theory. While many theories may, in fact, be models, not all are, for as A. Kaplan suggests, theories need not actu- ally exhibit the structure they assert the referent system to possess. On the other hand, models that do not purport to ex_ plain are not theories. Models can also be used E9 predict phenomena without necessarily explaining them. Models have long been considered the central necessity of seientific procedure. Models can increase understanding of the referent systems, aid in the development of theory, an . . d serve as a framework for experimentation. The disadvantages of modeling in general, stem from the model‘s artificiality, simplification, and idealization, and J.- «a “.4 .. (J) (I) K C) C. v "'. I n . ‘an .11‘ k “’Vfivgv ‘ 0 .5 1'" ., u l “P- bOAL I, - 1 u':v: Q. .V‘..~ V1 ‘5 ‘ . 6.. a. A '1"? .‘V- L. ‘u I :‘N- « I "V. 51 U 9 the consequent difficulties and dangers in making inferentflfl. leaps from a model to the real world. As a representation of a real system, the model's representativeness of that system is a crucial issue. Symbolic models are of special interest in social and administrative science and may take various forms, such as verbal, analytic (in the mathematical sense), or numerical. In addition, flow charts and similar pictorial models are bg coming increasingly popular. General Statement of Objectives The overall end purpose is to advance knowledge on the subject matter of Manufacturing Progress Functions. The prime objective of the study is to contribute a general symbolic-analytic model of the manufacturing progress phenomenon. Once the general model is established, an equally impog tant objective is to respond to the need for a coherent sys- tematic approach to be used in predicting the developments of the adaptation process in industrial concerns of almost any kind. Subobjectives. The foregoing general statement of purpose can be broken down into a number of layers of inves- tigation leading to the following more specific subobjec- tives: 10 A review of the literature that is of relevance to the objectives of the dissertation. An investigation of the theory of the manufacturing progress function aiming at a systematization of the existing body of knowledge, and at the deriva- tion of new theoretical results that will settle the question of the parameters estimation of the general model. The conception of a general symbolic-analytic model of the system adaptation phenomenon, including the development of a method for using the model to predict the course of future startups. The testing of the model in a number of real world situations by using data from.diverse industrial operations. The possibilities of implementing the model into practical use at firm level and national leve1.This signifies that the model can be practically inte- grated into the strategical planning of an industri a1 concern as well as used for macroeconomic decision-making. CHAPTER II THE EXISTING BODY OF KNOWLEDGE The present chapter contains a review of the histori- cal development of the manufacturing progress function, as well as a summary of the more important contributions to the progress curve literature which are of interest to the purpose of this dissertation. THE WRIGHT MODEL Historically this model is the first published attempt to relate labor hours and cumulative production.1 After fifteen years of empirical studies in the airframe industry Dr. T.P. Wright discovered the following hyperbolic func- tional relation: §'= ax.b (2.1) where, V = the cumulative average number of direct labor hours (or related cost) required per unit of output; x = the cumulative units of output; a = a parameter of the model, i.e., the labor hours required to produce the initial unit of production; (note that for x = 1, ll 12 §= 6(1)“b = a) b = a parameter of the model, i.e., a constant dependent upon the rate of progress.It is an index of the rate of decrease in labor hours during the start up (usually , 0<Iit: by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Conducted by Kenneth 15.. Ididdleton it deals with productivity changes.16 He noticed tiflzat: there was approximately a tripling of production per Unéiri-éhour during World War II and he attempts to identify the E<‘='=1c tors responsible for the observed productivity increment. no 'l' v l ..... with u... Ia'n - ‘4‘: I s.,. 1.. a._ l9 Middleton holds that the remarkable reduction of labor cost per unit is the result of technological changes such as increasing standardization of models, introduction of more sophisticated hand tools, and gauges. The rate of adoption of the new methods and new production techniques depends on management willingness to break with traditional methods. Kenneth A. Middleton also attempted to construct an industry wide production index by relating man-hours per pound of airframe and the cumulative production pounds in 17 the particular facility. He found that the decrease in Immrhours required per pound is similar for all types of air planes and that this index is useful for comparative purposes, although somewhat more man—hours per pound were required for a one engine fighter than for standard four engine bombers. ITuJ , using the above indicator of productivity, Middleton Concludes that the 70 per cent progress curve is more repre- Sentative of the aircraft industry during World War II than 18 the normally assumed 80 per-cent curve. It is worthy to Ilcrte that Middleton also has found considerable variation in the "slope" of the curve from one plane to another. Airframe Companies Publications Besides J.R. Crawford's contribution while working at the Lockheed Aircraft Corporation several progress-curve StImidies had also been prepared by other airframes companies - 19 In the forties, like Chance Vought Aircraft, Inc., and the 20 20 Boeing Airplane Company. The Chance Vought study was designed to instruct compa ny personnel in the application of the cumulative average curve, being similar to the Wright presentation, and hence will not be discussed herein. The study prepared at Boeing has some features relevant to the scope of this dissertation and will be briefly reviewed. The Experience Curve. This short book - one of the earliest company publications available - presents a concise statement of the unit curve, the cumulative average curve and the total curve as they were used by Boeing Cost Accoung ing Department. The pamphlet provides a mathematical preseng ation of the progress curve. From the equation for the unit curve, i.e., y = ax (2.5) time exact expression for the total labor hours expended in tile manufacturing of units one up to and including the nth. unit is given by: n y = a Z x. (2.6) SinCe equation (2.6) requires calculating every unit value iEITCHH l to p, an approximation was suggested by the authors, :Lt1 ‘which the limits of integration were formed by extending ‘t11ee range of the summation index so as to reduce the error 21 inherent in approximating a discrete function by a continuous function. Thus: n xi+0.5 yT = a Z xtb E a f x.b dx — n i=1 1 0.5 l-b l- = 1%,; [(xi + 0.5) - 0.5 b] (2.7) Studies Financed by the Air Force The Source Book of World War II Basic Data. This Air Force study of the progress curve published in 1947 has been the principal source of data for several empirical progress- 21 It contains data from every facility engaged curve studies. in the production of military models from 1940 through mid- 1945, presenting unit progress curves for each type of air- craft and one progress curve for £11 aircraft produced durfin; tflne war period. The curves obtained by using the least- Squares method represent direct labor hours per pound of ai; frame weight versus the cumulative number of airframes pro- duCed. The following table presents the parameters of the pIT’gress curve obtained in the Source Book of World War II Wgy 22 TABLE 2 . 1 PARAMETERS OF THE PROGRESS CURVE Type of Man-hours per Wright's "Slope" Pound at Unit Aircraft Number One (%) (a) Fighters 18.5 79 BoMbers 16.0 77 Transports 16. O 77 The Crawford-Strauss Study. An analysis of World War 11 production experience was made by Crawford 6: Strauss in 1947.22 The major purpose of the study has to do with the acceleration of airframe production; but since progress curves are important tools in any airframe production pro- gram, they are given careful attention. 23 The data was derived from the "Source Book" , and was baSed on the production data of 118 Worl War II models. Weighted average direct man-hours per pound at specific plane numbers were determined both for the industry as a whole and for each type of airplane (fighters, bombers and transports) . The resulting unit-progress-curve equation for a\11 models was -0.32668 x y = 14.3 (2.8) 23 From (2.8) and (2.3) it is easy to see that: a = 14.3 and Wright's "slope"=2-O°32668=0.797. It was probably this study that established the "80 per-cent rule" as standard in the airframe industry. Crawford & Strauss found that at least three major factors were responsible for the dispersion of the individ- ual progress curves around equation (2.8): (i) type of air- craft (fighters, bombers or transports); (ii)newness of the model and of the facility, and (iii) particular circumstances liproblems that surround production of each individual model. As to the relative position of the fighter, bomber and transport curves, they make the point that the bomber learn- :ing curve is the lowest because (i) bomber programs during lflorld War II were given priority over most other programs, and (ii) the size of bomber aircraft permitted greater access 111 the assembly Operation. The fighter curve is the highest because: (i) fighters are complex aircraft and (ii) their des ign changes often. In connection with the newness of models and facili- tieS, the 118 models were classified as: (l) Proven models prOduced in experienced facilities; (2) proven models pro- duced in new facilities, and (3) new models produced in new C”r’ experienced facilities. Weighted average curves like the Strauss c ' 1 ~-,¢..A3.~ nihb'u 'J' H’Alflfi‘ "0 4- nu 'L" fivyn , u‘... .. U . . . “1:4 ‘, ...,, 1‘. ' - :.‘.‘V:‘1 ‘5...‘.‘ 6 . AI ‘1 “II" n: l.‘ V-c ‘ 'I.|b '- 0. ‘3“!1 1 I)“: a 'U..‘ ; h. n "2‘ o "M. I . .I“ . .V‘ :1: ? ..n "u q . 's U: 24 previous ones were obtained for each class above. On the basis of visual inspection of such curves Crawford and Strauss concluded that: The early units of a proven model produced in an experienced facility require fewer man-hours per pound than the average for all aircrafts. This advantage is not maintained, however, after a few hundred units have been produced. The progress curve for proven models pro— duced in new facilities follows the average curve for all aircraft until a few hundred units have been delivered,after Iflfich the former curve falls slightly below the latter. The curve for new models produced in either new or old facilities is consistently higher than the average curve for all air- craft. These results are summarized in Table 2.2 The third factor - or cluster of factors - which has been found to affect the level of progress is described as the special circumstances and problems that surround produg “tion Of each individual model. Some of these are listed by the authors as: (i) The length of the production run, (ii) nflnether or not the model has been engineered for mass produg tZion, (iii) whether or not proven engineering was available When production started, (iv) whether or not high production was started from low production tools, (v) introduction of design changes, (vi) whether or not old tools were available when production started, (vii) availability of materials or component parts, (viii) availability of experienced manpower, (ix) relative priority attached to a given model, (X) effi‘ cieency of operating controls,(xi) frequency of scheduled 9".. 0”!“ . .- mlu u‘vu.‘ M”: m . i’ .Jt‘ . Etc. «:4 0- 25 TABLE 2.2 INFLUENCE OF THE NEWNESS OF MODELS AND FACILITIES ON THE RELATIVE POSITION OF PROGRESS CURVES facility old model new curve is lower than the avg. curve only up to a few hundred units curve follows the avg. Old curve until a few hundred units; then it falls below curve is higher curve is higher new than the avg. curve than the avg. curve for all planes for all planes. «ahanges and degree of pressure attached to a program, (xii) (economical and uneconomical use of outside production,(xiii) degree to which feeder plants and outlying areas were uti- ldiZed in order to tap a wider labor market, (xiv) whether or ‘acyt the plant layout was favorable to the production of a Particular model and (xv) availability of specialized high 24 PrOduction machinery. The authors conclude that it would be difficult to theasure the effect of special circumstances or to weigh dlrect labor progress curves and industry averages for these I ..!IA 5 .ti'* ”3 ‘ A ..4 o no; “ «1 VI.‘ 26 factors. However, they believe that the industry average es- tablished in the study presents a reliable picture of the relationship of direct man-hours per pound to cumulative prg duction during World War II, since they include the cumula- tive effect of all particular circumstances and problems which surrounded the production program, for each model. The Stanford-B Model. After World War II a number of economists and econometricians became interested in learning curve research. The Air Force had also come to recognize the importance of the progress curve, and sponsored several research projects with private organizations to develop further the application of the theory. Probably the best known of these were the studies carried out by the Stanford Research Institute and by the Rand Corporation. Since the latter were mainly published after 1950 they will be consid- ered in the next section. Under contract with the United States Air Force, Air Imateriel Command, the Stanford Research Institute made a Study on the Relationships for Determining the Optimum Expan- W g the Elements 9_f_ a Peace-Time Aircraft Procurement lixllgggg in order to determine the means of measuring the Inakimrum rates in aircraft production programs. Since the max Zinmufllexpansibility rates depend to a large extent on the 1fate of manufacturing time reduction, a decision was made to atlé'llyze the direct man-hour progress curve. According to the fiI'lal report the project has resulted in an improved 27 relationship involving direct-labor hours, airframe unit 25 weight and cumulative production. The Stanford-B formula or the learning formula with a B-factor can be expressed as follows: y = a (x + B)n (2.9) where: y = direct man-hours required for cumulative unit number x. B = equivalent-units of experience available at the start of a manufacturing program; 1ng10, 4 being a typical value. n has a similar meaning as the b-exponent in the Wright model. Usually -l‘1fllt. Berghell suggests that if the cumulative average man- llcnu'data are plotted against cumulative output for, say, ifcnu'different aircraft, the resulting slopes of these ave; age curx37es will not be significantly different from one aucther (i.e. , the _b_ values will be similar), but the le_vgl_ 0f the curves (i.e. , the g values) will be different. The a; ‘ . . . pread between the curves can be reduced by d1v1ding direct 32 labor hours by airframe weight. Since Berghell assumes that airframe weight remains the same for each plane, the slopes do not change. Berghell argues that a heavier airframe will generally require fewer labor-hours per pound than a lighter aflrframe at the same cumulative unit number. Therefore,it is expected that, in terms of direct labor-hours per unit the curves for the heaviest airframes appear at a higher level, but in terms of direct labor—hours per pound, the curves for the heaviest airframes are on a lower level. Berghell then reads off the direct labor-hours per pound at units 50 and 100 for the four aircraft, plots these eight values against airframe weight on logarithmic grids, and obtains two linear curves showing the relationship between direct labor-hours per pound and airframe weight, one curve for unit number 50 and the other curve for unit number 100. The man-hours per pound of airframe values for any new airplane are then obtained at units 50 and 100 by interpolation for the given airframe'weight. These two cumulative average man-hour per IDOund points are all that is needed to draw the cumulative érverage progress curve for the new airplane. I.M. Laddon. Laddon was Executive Vice-President of (3cxmolidated Vultee Aircraft Corporation. The article he prg Sents contains a description of change in the production iftnumion as the total quantity to be produced by a company jLE‘inCreased. The author explains the difference in produc- tiixnlmethods when sixty units are to be produced as opposed t: . ‘3 several thousand. The company performed much better than 33 36 the customary 80 per-cent curve. G.W. Carr. One writer who believes the progress curwa 37 should take on the "S" shape is G.W. Carr. He found that, in several cases, the rate of labor decrease in a given air- frame varied, yielding different values of b_instead of one constant value. Carr did not offer a formal relationship embodying these conclusions, but another modified model,the "Boeing hump-curve”,is a recognition of his findings.38 The concavity early in the series was also recognized by the Stanford Research Institute.39 Carr argues that such concavi ty results from hiring inexperienced crews at different points in time during the production of the first several lots of airframes. The empirical data available to P.Guibert from the French airframe industry apparently exhibited the 40 same early concavity. THE FIFTIES A number of decisive contributions to the theory and (levelopment of progress curves were published in the 19505. There was an effort by some researchers to extend the concept 12<>other labor-intensive industries outside the airframe industry. Also, studies continued to be financed by the :ALJJ'Force in several research institutes of the country. 34 Extensions of the Concept Outside the Airframe Industry Werner Hirsch's Studies and Research. Hirsch's stud- ies were mainly published in Econometrica and the Review of 41 42 _— Economics and Statistics. In one of his works, Hirsch computed a total of 22 empirical progress functions, based upon historical data from one of the country's largest ma- chine tool manufacturers. The results of the study may be summarized as follows: (i) The hypothesis of linearity (when in logarithmic coordinates) between the labor per unit and cumulg tive output was confirmed for all cases. In 17 out of 22 cases, the correlation coefficient was found greater than 0.85. In only one instance this coef- ficient was as small as 0.59. (ii) The 22 empirical progress functions revealed a negative slope, i.e., labor hours per unit decremx: as cumulative production izcreases. (iii) The average progress ratiz 3 was 19.3 per cent and the range (16.5 - 24.8). (iv) Another important conclusion was that different kinds of operations exhibit different "slopes". Thus, the 80 per cent learning curve cannot be universally applied.In fact, Hirsch has shown that assembly operations are characterized by signifi- cantly higher progress ratios than are machining operations. An explanation offered was that in the 35 former the labor content is higher than in the latter. 45 (v) Compounded experience. In a paper ,Armen Alchimn suggested that older,more experienced manufactunhm; facilities exhibit a greater rate of decline than do new facilities.To test this hypothesis Hirsch used the data of a manufacturer who had produced more than 15 lots of a certain semi-automatic tur- ret lathe, in the same plant, when he initiated production of a greatly improved model. In more than one respect the new model resembled the previ ous one, and work on the first appeared to have constituted valuable experience. In a sense, then, the improved model was built with the help of much previously accumulated experience. Thus, the ques- tion was whether the progress ratio of the new lathe would be significantly greater than that of the old one. Progress functions for both lathes were calculated, and progress ratios (both for as- sembly and machining work) of the model built with the compounded experience were found significantly larger than those of the first model. This conclu- sion is consistent with Alchian's "experience" hypothesis. Hirsch was probably one of the first researchers to reg ognize the value of the manufacturing progress function 36 outside the airframe industry.His contribution represents one of few published empirical studies in non-airframe industries. 46 Stanley E. Bryan's Study. In an insightful article Professor Bryan related the manufacturing progress phenome- non to value concepts and collected data on its existence in a large company's footwear plant. He points out that in certain types of procurement like the contracting for spe- cial and non-standard equipment, competition ceases to be a decisive influence in price determination. In such cases , pricing becomes a matter of negotiation. In negotiation, price is related to cost to a greater extent than to the util ity of the product. Consequently, the method of estimating and compiling cost of producing an item becomes crucial both to the buyer and to the seller. If the manufacturer does not take into account the progress phenomenon in his estimate he would quote unrealistically high cost on the labor portion of the contract. If the buyer is not aware of that phenomenon he would accept the seller's estimate as being fair.47 According to Professor Bryan's data, this particular manufacturer of footwear experienced an approximately 90 per cent "slope" PrOgress curve. 48 The Schulz and Conway Study. The existence of the PIOgress phenomenon had been known for some time at IBM- Endicott, but until 1955 no systematic study had ever been made to determine whether the decline in direct-labor hours per unit of output followed any predictable pattern. With 37 this in mind, a group of graduate students from the Industri a1 Engineering School at Cornell University, under the guid- ance of Dr. Andrew Schulz, Jr., defined the following objec- tives for a study of labor hours reduction trends: (i) To furnish a better basis for product pricing, product replace- ment, and decision to manufacture. (ii) To provide a better basis for estimating and planning the amounts of space and manpower required by a proposed manufacturing program, and (iii) To help in the planning and budgeting of engineering or other staff effort for cost reduction activities. The study carried out to develop the Manufacturing Frog ress Function consisted in:(i) The collection of a number of series of labor hours with the corresponding production quap tities, together with all the supporting information that could be obtained, such as: engineering changes, manufactur- ing methods and tooling changes, personnel turnover ratesguui the like. (ii) The analysis of the information so as to assg ciate cause and effect, and to isolate the relevant variables, and (iii) The generalization of the results obtained from the analysis. The conclusions reached were based on a detailed study of an accounting machine and verified by sample checks 0n.other IBM machines. The following factors were found to influence the de- Cline in labor hours per unit with increased cumulative (l) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) 38 The degree of similarity of a machine to a prede- cessor or to other machines produced had a signif- icant effect on the rate of progress: the less similarity, the greater the rate of progress.49 Single-product departments exhibit greater rates of progress than do multi-product departments. Product redesign, and tool and methods improvements result in a greater rate of progress. Increasing rates of production as a machine program accelerates result in economies. Management progress in scheduling and supervision results in a greater rate of progress. Increased planning prior production will result in a lower initial cost and a reduced rate of progress. Worker learning through repetition, changes in method, and reduction in scrap and rework result in a greater rate of progress. According to the authors of the study, the last item has either been overemphasized or erroneously indicated as the main causal factor in the literature prior to 1959. They indicate that operator learning in the true sense of perfor- mance of a fixed task is of negligible importance in most manufacturing progress. Changes in tooling, methods and Pr0duct design that are usually the result of management and 39 engineering effort rather than operator learning in any sense, have been found much more significant. Terminology. An understanding of the following termi nology will facilitate further discussion: (i) Manufacturing Progress Function Hours - Those hours over and above the estimated hours which are caused by the introduction of a new unit into a manufac— turing system. (ii) Manufacturing Progress Function Cost - The cost associated with the MPF hours. (iii) Ultimate Unit pf Production - That point in cumulg tive production at which the reduction in manufac- turing hours per unit from the first unit in the month to the last unit for the month is between 2% and 3% and thus can be considered nominal. (iv) Ultimate Hours - The estimated hours required to produce the unit at the ultimate unit of productnni. (v) Standard Parts - Component parts used in previous machines. (vi) Labor Value Index (LVI) - A measure of a component part value determined as follows: Estimated unit Parts usage No.of machs. produced x x hours at ultimate vper machine per month at ultimafla LVI u 40 Problem of Aggregation. In order to make the study, it was necessary to accumulate a great deal of historical data on manufacturing and assembly hours for the machines and units under consideration. An analysis of the data showed that different types of operations exhibited varying progrems trends. As a result, the operations were broken down as fol- lows : (1) Final Assembly Operations: (a) Mechanical Assembly; (b) Wiring;(c) Inspection, Test and Clear trouble. (2) Sub-Assembly Operations: (a) Single-product deparp ments; (b) Multi-product departments. (3) Manufactured Parts: (a) Standard Parts; (b) New Parts, further subdivided into: New Parts with LVI > 140 and New Parts with LVI 5.140. These breakdowns are referred to as categories. In analysing the data further for determining the MPF curves,the data was handled by categories for a machine. For example , when studying the trends in cost reduction for parts having LVIgl40, all parts for a given machine having LVI_<_140 were handled as one figure, rather than as individual components.It was felt that the study of separate components WOUld tend to give misleading results, whereas a group of Parts would be more representative of the category. The intent was 59 break the labor content down into EéEggories that have reasonably uniform behavior with regard 41 E2.ERE £222.2£ progress. Such classifications, however, are subject to the criticism that for application of the function much subjective judgement is required until more knowledge fl; gained.51 Form of the Model and Parameter Determination. From the investigation of historical data Schultz and Conway adopted the Crawford model for the manufacturing progress curve 2 Y = ax (2.11) where : ‘13 II the direct-labor hours required to produaa the initial unit of production. b = a constant dependent upon the rate of progress. x = cumulative unit of production yL= lot-average direct-labor hours per unit of output. This same curve when plotted on full logarithmic paper he- comes a straight line. Such line will be designated by the term progress line. The method of least squares was used so as to obtain the optimum fit of the progress line to the raw data. To this end, a code was developed in order to compute the following information for g_ac_h of thezaforementioned catg gories: (1) The a parameter; (2) The p parameter; (3) The Value of y for the thousandth unit;(this permits the plotting );(4) The 0f the least squares trend line between a and leOO' 42 Wright "slope" percentage; (5) The confidence limits; (6) The coefficients of correlation of the data. Plotting the Progress Curve for a New Machine. -The application of the "slope" percentages thus derived requires judgement for assembly operations. Since such values were obtained mainly from the study of a particular machine (call it the basis machine), all new machines to which a manufactup ing progress function study is to be applied must be compared to the basis machine as to complexity and novelty, as well as to any similar predecessors to the machine under consider- ation. Empirical tables were developed that permit such com- parisons and the final selection of the Wright "slope" for a given category of operations. In such tables, the greater the camplexity of the focused machine as compared to the basis machine, the greater the rate of progress to be expe- rienced in future manufacturing.Also, the greater the similap ity with respect to a predecessor or to other machines pro- duced, the smaller will be the rate of progress. Two other factors, namely the amount of tooling completed prior to initial production, and the rate pf production at the ulti- mate month influence the "slope" determination for some cate_ gories. In the referred tables, the greater the percentage 0f tooling completed prior the inception of production, the smaller will be the future rate of progress for the category involved. In addition, the greater the rate of production scheduled for the ultimate month, the greater the rate of Progress. 43 The next problem in plotting the progress curve for a new machine is the determination of the ultimate unit of prg duction. As a result of the study carried out by the Cornell Group, the following locations of ultimate units were recom- mended: (1) Manufactured Parts - 12 months; (2) Final Assem- bly - 18-24 months. Increased complexity, rate of production at ultimate and novelty of a machine will dictate the ulti- mate units at or near the 24 month end of the range. These relationships are presented in tables similar to those em- ployed in selecting the wright "slope" for the category. 52 In a paper, Schreiner describes the technique used at IBM-Endicott to apply the Manufacturing Progress Function Procedure developed by the Cornell Group to their manufactup ing activities. In order to plot the progress curve for arm»: machine it would be sufficient to know the values for the parameters §_and p. However,this procedure requires the knowl edge of the direct-labor hours consumed by the production of the initial unit (i.e., the geparameter). Since knowledge of the manufacturing progress function cost is required p319; to the inception of production,this information would not be available. A different approach is used instead. When a machine has been designed and tested, Cost Eng; nearing prepares an estimate on the machine (using,for exam- ple, predetermined times). These estimates are carried out for each component, sub-assembly, and final assembly by ope; ation assuming optimum conditions, i.e., the Methods Engineer 44 considers all tooling complete and operator learning also complete. The estimates are then separated into the foremen- tioned seven categories. Next, considering one category at a time, the direct-labor hours for the category are totalled This value, yu, is represented in Figure l by the horizontal 53 line at which the progress curve should level off. The next step is to determine, in units of production, when the progress curve is expected to level off, that is,to 9) Category I b = Tan ¢ Mfg.Hours/Unit < X 1.14 X Cumulative Units of Production Log-Log Plot FIGURE 1 Plotting the Progress Line For a Given Category 45 select the ultimate unit of production. This is done by comparing the machine being studied to predecessor machines for which the progress rates are known . As mentioned be- fore, three characteristics are employed in the selection of ultimates : (1) The relative complexity or difficulty of the operations ; (2) The novelty or newness of the machine as compared to earlier operations ; (3) The number of units to be produced per month at ultimate . These char- acteristics permit to obtain the entries to the proper tables of ultimates , already referred . Having selected the ultimate unit of production x it is now possible u 3 to locate point (xu , yu) of the progress line (see Figure 1). After the mathematical slope of the progress line through point (xu,yu) is determined, it will be straightfor- ward to draw the progress curve. Again the focused machine is compared to previous machines as to complexity of operations and novelty. The comparisons together with the expected rate 0f production at ultimate yield entries to the proper tables Of "slopes" already mentioned. Since the Wright "slope" is given by equation (2.3), it is easy to see that the angle ¢ between the progress line and the horizontal axis can be calculated by: ¢ = tg-1[log(wrigh§o: glope {] (2.12) 46 The knowledge of angle (1) makes it possibleto draw the progress line through point (xu,yu) and to determine the Q value for the category (Figure 1). Knowing the g and p param eters for each of the categories it is possible to draw the progress curve on arithmetic paper (Figure 2). Hrs/Unit 4' Mfg. c2 Cumulative Units of Production FIGURE 2 Progress Curve in Arithmetic Graph Airframe Companies Publications Cost-estimating manuals and the results of progress- -Curve studies have been prepared by the Glenn L. Martin Com 55 54 panyq by Northrop Aircraft, Inc., North American Aviation 56 57 Inc., and the Boeing Airplane Company. The Martin. and Northrop studies were designed to trafi1 company personnel in the use of the cumulative average curve. 47 The North American publication was prepared for the instrug tion of the purchasing personnel in the use of the learning curve in procurement of subcontracted parts. It is a concise statement of how a purchasing agent may apply the learning curve to the many procurement problems which arise in the course of his duty. The latter three studies are similar to the Wright presentation, and hence, will not be discussed further. The Boeing publication which was authored by W.F.Brown presents the learning curve as it is used by Boeing, in relg tively easy to understand form. In speaking about the produg tion of automobile bodies, the author holds that whereas time reduction continues to take place even after a large cumula- tive output has been reached, this reduction will be insig- nificant and may take a long time to realize.58 This is contrary to the opinion held by Boeing personnel in the past, which was:after a certain number of units have been produced, the progress curve reaches a plateau.59 It should be remembered that most of the publications, do not contain empirical data to support statements made , bUt presumably, the statements are based on company H 0 experience". Studies Financed by the Air Force The RAND Corporation of Stanta Monica, California,under contract with the Air Force, has prepared several studies of fi‘l‘. “’1‘ v- . u.» Is‘ . 'n! r? 'F . ,u- ’v -. eP v 1. u... .- an. -.a I. a --5 no» 4 1.... a 4” ~.-_“ ' n "'v- q. u 'D‘ .1. _ '- ..,’ ....“m: 2‘: f' ' -,‘ .“ . .0 1.3.” ' 1 b_‘ ', h J (I) [U 48 the progress curve based on the same data that were used in the Crawford-Strauss and Stanford studies already reviewed. Of interest to this dissertation are the studies by Alchian and Asher, to be summarized in the following paragraphs. 60 A.A1chian's Study . This study investigates several characteristics of the new airframe startups that ocurred during World War II. In regards to the progress curve, Alchian poses several questions, the most pertinent of which are (1) How long does the decline in unit labor hours contip ue for a given model? (2) Does the progress curve correspond fundamentally to a linear function on log-log scale? and (3) Does one progress curve with- given parameters 3 and p adequately describe the consumption of direct-labor hours per pound of airframe for all models? As to the first question, no cessation in the manhour decline was evident to the author. This conclusion was based on visual examination of the graphs presented in the Source Book pf World war II Basic Data: Airframe Industry, Volume I, already cited. As to the second question, no attempt is made in Alchian's study to establish whether or not a suitable altep native exists to the linear progress curve because of the inadequate amount of data available for the study. It should be added that fitting the Crawford model to the data via least squares regression analysis yielded correlation coeffi cients exceeding 0.80 in the twenty-two startups analyzed. 49 In answer to the third question, Alchian's study re- veals that the slope and height of a single progress curve do not represent the unit man-hour expenditures required for all aircraft models. Different values of parameters 3 and p were found for different airframes. Moreover, classifying the airframes by type (fighter, bomber, and so on) still resulted in diverse g and p_values within each class. These findings appear to erase any doubt about the validity of the "universal 80% — learning curve". HLAsher's Study . In the second RAND study, Asher at— tempts to demonstrate that the progress curve in linear terms does not describe accurately the relationship between unit manhours and the cumulative output. 1 To show that the prog- ress curve departs from linearity after a certain cumulative production number has been reached, Asher examines hourly data for a number of individual producing departments. It is concluded that the linear approximation is reasonable for all departments for an initial quantity of airframes. However, the different departments exhibit non-similar slopes for'these linear .segments . If an analysis of actual data reveals that departmental progress curves do, in fact, have signif- icantly different slopes from each other, then the unit curve (the sum of the departmental curves) cannot be linear.Instead, With linear but nonparallel departmental curves, the compos- ite unit curve must be convex on logarithmic grids and must aP'Proach as a limit the flattest of the departmental curves. This mathematical consideration alone is sufficient to 50 demonstrate Asher's point of view. He then, proceeded to sum the department curves. The aggregate unit curve shows that it begins to level off at approximately unit 125, and the author claims that if a linear extrapolation was made between units 100 to 1,000, the estimating error would be around 25 per-cent. With some reservation about the limited samples examined in the study, Asher concludes that beyond certain values of cumulative output, the progress curves examined develop convexity and thus the conventional linear progress cannot be considered an accurate description of the zglatiop ship between unit labor hours and cumulative output. In examining the continuous-declining characteristics of the progress curve, Asher found definite discontinuities in the individual shop data at high cumulative outputs. In addition, the discontinuities persisted even when the data from different departments were aggregated into total labor hour expenditure for an airframe. Asher also investigated the "slopes" that occur in different producing departments. Using the Crawford model,he fOund that an aggregate of sheet metal work, machine shop Work, and materials processing are characterized by "slope" Percentages varying from 76% to 87%. Major and final assembly Work exhibited a faster rate of manhour decrease, yielding "slopes" between 69% and 75%. The studies by Alchian and Asher, together with Hirschfis study in the machine-tool industry.may represent the most . 1 "PA’ p Janis IR... ‘ “N own...» 3 ~ .Iu.’ ~ "' 5.11“ I In. ' , . :~ 1"; ‘4 5..., V I 'A p .35 .. u .H ‘nt ‘1 \‘ 51 objective and rigorous empirical investigation of the prog- ress curve concept produced in the fifties. Other contributions Two other contributions are worth mentioning in this connection, namely the articles by Koen63 and Andreas.64 Francis T. Koen, of the Missile Systems Division, Raytheon Company, uses the manufacturing progress function as the basis for what he calls "Dynamic Evaluation". With it, he is able to (l) predict production trouble, (2) estimate manufacturing costs, (3) check estimates and budget perfor- mance, (4) predict personnel requirements, (5) help determine make-or-buy decisions, (6) determine relation between standard cost and quantity values, and (7) establish budgets and optimum production schedules. Frank J. Andress believes that "product innovation" is one of the primary criterions upon which the usefulness of the manufacturing progress function should be based. This includes situations where both major and minor design changes are often incorporated while the product is in production, Where new products are frequently introduced, and/or where there are frequent production runs at well-spaced intervals. Sueh companies would be at the upper end of the manufacturing Progress function and could, thus, realize the maximum advap tages of the improvement rate. 52 THE SIXTIES AND SEVENTIES In the last fifteen years there is evidence ofairenewed intepest::inl the subject of progress functions, particulap 1y outside the airframe industry. The contributions in this period are of a somewhat diversified nature. There are pioneering extensions of the concept to machine-intensive industries as well as to other labor-intensive industries not studied before. At least one leading company in the field of electronic data processing systems continues to develop and apply the theory of progress functions in its manufac- turing operations. The progress curve is also demonstrated to be valid in service activities like overhaul and mainte- nance. Furthermore, their users seem more careful in iden- tifying its caveats and possible deviations. Extension to Machine-Intensive Manufacture Baloff is best known for extending the use of the learning curve model to machine-intensive production 65 sYstems as well as to other labor intensive manuface 66 tures different from the airframe industry. He suggests the use of a modified version of the model in highly mechanized manufacture (steel, glass-manufacturing, Paper products and electrical-products)? Some years later the startup model is extended to three examples of labor intensive manufacture - automobile assembly, apparel man- . 68 Ufacture and the production of large musical instruments. 53 Baloff is highly skeptical with respect to past ap- proaches used in parameter estimation. As indicated earlier, only a few solutions to the parameter prediction have been guoposed in the literature. A well known approach to the estimation of the p param eter is to assume simply that its value will remain constant for all startups in an industry, regardless of changes in product type, processing facility, or company origin. This assumption, which was apparently quite popular in the air- frame industry at one time, continues to find support in the literature.69 The violence to reality that results has been stressed by Baloff.7O The assumption of a constant p_paramg ter is inconsistent with the results of empirical examina- tions of a large number of airframe startups that took place 71 during World War II and in postwar years. A more refined approach is based on the assumption that the startups of similar products or processes will experience identical startup curves. This approach essentially uses the empirically derived parameters of past startups as best esti mates of one or both of the parameters in a future startupcxf a physically similar product or process. Unfortunately, expg rience suggests that variations in parameter values are not to be explained this simply. It has been shown by Baloff that the startups of steel processes that are physically very Similar exhibit significantly different i and p_parameters, 54 even if the comparison is restricted to a single company in 72 the industry or to a single plant. Interplant comparisons of the startups of certain classes of airframes have yielded equivalent findings.73 A third approach that has been mentioned in the lite; ature represents a refinement of the similarity concept. Here the focus is on recognizing and evaluating variables or factors that influence the values of one or both of the parap eters for a given startup.74 An evaluation of these factors in relation to experience with past startups could then puesumably serve as a basis for generating estimates of the umdel parameters for a future startup. According to Baloff, there has been no published account of the reliability of this type of factor approach. Lacking such information, its Utility in practice must remain an open question.75 Baloff argues that a different approach to the param- eter estimation problem is suggested by the existence of a s"trong relationship between the g and 13 parameters among different startups in the steel and airframe industries and ill 'the results of a laboratory research on group problemr sOlving. Though still tentative, this relationship appears it‘3 ‘hold promise of being developed into an objective means ()1? estimating the p parameter of the model, given a measurg BEIGEtit of the initial productivity of a startup. The existence of the relationship was initially reporp eaci ‘bw'Asher in the airframe industry nearly two decades ago. 55 Asher found a strong direct correlation between the g and p parameters of the startup model among 12 postwar startups of fighter-class airframes. The strength of the relationship observed by Asher was notable, allowing him to fit the fol- lowing model to the 12 pairs of parameter values: log b = log m + n log a (2.13) Following the lead of Asher, Baloff extended this parameter model approach to the steel industry and to the glass manufacturing industry.77 The results of a laboratory experiment on group problem-solving also provided Baloff evidence of an inverse correlation between the parameters of the startup model in a learning situation that is similar to an industrial startup.78 Later he would come to find support for the parameter model approach in laboratory experiments 79 With group adaptation to a business game and in automobile 80 Startups. Baloff's empirical contributions may well represent a tnI‘ning point in the theory and application of the manufac- tut‘ing progress function. COutributions by IBM Personnel After the Schultz and Conway study already reviewed in an earlier section, IBM personnel became very active in the -- S‘~:'-1>ject of progress functions. Articles by P.B. Metz, J.G E15 learning is used in a computer program to observe the Ireissults of varying the number of lines employed. The result jLEB the generation of a specific progress function model for Eaéicth product profile thus simulated. Therefore,the progress islltiction can become more useful when the model for the C‘, q- .l 59 specific product is predictable. From the simulation of various product profiles Russell concludes that the addition and subtraction of parallel lines of production do create significant deviations in the progrems function. The author believes that these changes form the major trend lines of the progress function as applied to a specific product. In addition, Russell points out that the effects of major product improvements, operational problems, inventory policy, lead-time changes, and modifications in accounting method will also cause deviations to the progress function. Each should be evaluated separately and its effect overlaid on the trend lines of the product profile. The study by Russell represents a pioneering effort towards using simp. lation methodology in the investigation of adaptation phenom ena. 0ther Contributions For their intrinsic interest and relevance to the field 0f manufacturing progress functions, four more contributions wi-Il.l be concisely reviewed in the subsequent paragraphs. 85 Setting Management Goals‘. James M. White of S‘tevens Institute of Technology, believes that the manufac- turing progress function is highly useful in almo‘st‘any situa- t:ion in which there is some criterion by which to measure the improvement phenomenon,and which is initially in what Would be <3<>Ilsidered an "uncontrolled state". Possible cases that would 60 fall within this category are:(l) Reduction of losses due to waste, (2) reduction of scrap and rejects, (3) decreasing accident rates, (4) increasing capacity because of poor plan ning and control of resources, (5) reducing clerical errors, and other situations. In his article White demonstrates how to use the progress curve in setting goals for improvement in waste control. The other cases above mentioned are potential situations where progress curve theory could be used to predict the expected rate of improvement thus permitting the achievement of worthwhile results in management planning. 86 Multi-Product Industries. Paul F. Williams , an in- dustrial engineer for United Control Corporation, holds that the manufacturing progress function can be a very beneficial tool for multi-product industries. He claims there are two general classes of application of the function. The first is fOr use on "initial quantities" of production. This would be uSed for scheduling a new product, or one on which insuffi- ‘Iient records were kept by which to make a manufacturing jpI-‘Qgress function. The second classification would be for t'fiallow-on-quantities". This would be used for a product pI‘esently being produced,or one on which sufficient records T”ere kept by which to make a progress function . In addition, t:11£a function is valuable for the following reasons : (1) It EDITCJVides a systematic, consistent , and objective method (’13 forecasting production information ; (2) It can be llssqu to estimate average production costs of both "initial" El'I'ld "follow-on-quantities";(3) It is a graphic technique and, bu 61 thus, easy to use; (4) It can be used by management as a yani stick to measure manufacturing performance, and (5) When it is properly applied, it can minimize the error of estimatimn. Petroleum Refining. WLB.Hirschmann,believes that the progress curve is an underlying natural characteristic of organized activity, just as the normal curve is an accurate depiction of normal, random distribution of anything, from human I.Q.'s to the size of tomatoes.87 He plotted the per- formance of individual catalytic cracking units at a point in time against their age at that time. The dependent vari- able was current capacity expressed as a percentage of design capacity. The first unit in 1958 was one and one-half years old and by that time had achieved approximately 116% 0f design capacity. The second unit was four years old and had achieved about 125% of design capacity. The older units Show that the performance rapidly improved in the first few Years, and continued at a slower rate in later years.Another Sllotting of successive annual points for an individual cracking unit indicates growth occurring in a step-wise fashion. However, the pattern of improvement resembles the ilrrverse of a progress function on arithmetic paper. If the parameters are changed so that the number of (1&1378 to process 100,000 barrel is plotted against cumulated t:}11:oughput on a logarithmic paper, a declining straight line (:Eitl be drawn through the points as indicated by Figure 3. 62 ‘ A3. of Unit (you-a) Days Par 100,000 Barrels o v r v v v vvvr V7 r v vfirfr o 10 100 moo ' ' -- '" Canaan's 14111101: Bun-01- Run ' ' ' ' "1'. 7 FIGURE 3 Progress Line For a Catalytic Cracking Unit This Line has a slope of about 9070, as might be expected from a machine-paced operation which involves comparatively little dinsect labor. Hirschmann further states that a manufacturing progress fliltlction can be determined for any industry. A logarithmic plot of man-hours per barrel versus cumulated barrels of Qt‘ude oil refined in the United States since 1860 was made. He found similar declines for the United States basic steel industry and for the United States electric power industry. Hirschmann'ssmdy indicates that the manufacturing progress 63 function is not only applicable to the aircraft industry,but also to non-aircraft industries.Together with the studies by Baloff, it represents a pioneering effort towards extending the progress curve model to highly automated industries where the adaptation phenomenon might be thought to be either non- existent or too small to be of value. Limits of the Progress Curve. An article by W. J. Abernathy and K. Wayne looks at the progress curve in a new way.88 It shows the unforeseen consequences of following the strategy of reducing costs in a product through steady in- creases in volume: rising fixed costs,a narrowly specialized work group, and a withered capacity for innovation, to name just three. To illustrate the changes that accompany a cost-minimizing strategy, the authors use the case of Ford Motor Company and its model T. The kindscfifchanges that took place can be grouped into six categories - product; capital equipment and process technology; task characteristics and process structure; scale; material inputs; and labor. Each category is briefly described as follows. (1) Product: Standardization increases, models change less frequently and the product line offers less diversity. As the implementation of the strategy continues, the total contribution improves with acceptance of lower margins accompanying larger volume. 64 (2) Capital Equipment and Process Technology: Vertical integration expands and specialization in process equipment, machine tools,and facilities increase. The rate of capital investment rises while the flexibility of these investments declines. (3) Task Characteristics and Process Structure: The throughput time improves and the division of labor is extended as the production process is rational- ized and oriented more toward a line-flow operation. The amount of direct supervision decreases as the labor input falls. (4) Scale: The process is segmented to take advantage of economies of scale. (5) Material Inputs: Through either vertical integra- tion or capture of sources of supply, material inputs come under control. Costs are reduced by forcing suppliers to develop materials that meet process needs. (6) Labor: the heightening rationalization of the process leads to greater specialization in labor skills and may ultimately lessen workers' pride in their jobs and concern for product quality. The authors point out that the same pattern of change in the six categories that characterizes Ford history also describes ‘Periods of major reduction in other industries. 65 Implications for Management. According to Abernathy and Wayne, management needs to recognize that conditions sthp ulating innovation are different from those favoring effi- cient, high-volume, established operations. The unfortunate implication is that product innovation is the enemy of cost efficiency and vice-versa. The authors point two courses of action that some major companies have followed. One is to maintain efforts to continue development of the existing high- -volume product lines. This requires setting the industry pace in periodically inaugurating major product changes whiha stressing cost reduction via the learning curve between model changes. This course of action, exemplified by IBM, amountstn maintaining comparatively less efficient overall operations. The second course of action is to take a ,decentralized ap- proach in which separate organizations or plants in the cor- porate framework adopt different strategies within the same line of business. One organization in the company will pursue profits with a traditional product to the limit of the learp ing curve while othersvfill.develop new products and processes. SUMMARY The present chapter contains a review of the histori- cal development of the manufacturing progress function and a summary of the more important contributions to the progress curve literature that are relevant“ to this dissertation. 66 Although the progress curve was discovered in 1922, it was largely unknown until World War II. T.P. Wright is given credit for originating the formu- lation of the progress curve theory in 1936. His statement, that cumulative average man-hours per unit decline by a constant percentage every time the output is doubled, re- mains the most popular formulation in existence. In the forties, a number of modifications of the origi nal model were proposed. However, empirical verification of the modified models has been fragmentary and they have found little acceptance. In spite of this, Crawford contributedtim "unit" learning curve and noticed that different "slopes" might exist for different airframes. Ie is probably the first author to perceive the link between rate of progress ha a job and its degree of complexity and novelty. Several relevant contributions to the development of progress curves were published in the 19503. There is an effort by some researchers like Hirsch, Bryan, Schultz and Conway to extend the concept to labor—intensive industries other than the airframe industry. In addition, studies con- tinued to be financed by the United States Air Force in.some research institutes of the country. The studies by Alchian and Asher, in the airframe industry,together with Hirsch's Study in the machine-tool industry,and Schultz and Conway's research in manufacturing of electronic and electro-mechani- cal products may well represent the most objective and 67 rigorous empirical investigation of the progress curve con- cept produced in the fifties. The last fifteen years have seen some pioneering extep sions of the progress curve concept to machine-intensive industries as well as to diverse labor-intensive industries. The studies carried out by Baloff constitute the most comprg hensive investigation of the progress function in the men- tioned period. Review of the Main Hypotheses It is worthwhile to recapitulate the principal hypoth- eses raised by the forementioned authors and generally accepted: (1) Linearity , when in logarithmic coordinates , be- tween the 1abor per unit and cumulative output was generally confirmed except in Asher's study. (2) There is no one single progress curve that can be universallyapplied to all types of operations involved in the manufacturing of a given product. Also, there is not a curve that .can represent_ the adaptation phenomenon for all products in a given firm or industry. (3) Assembly operations experiment significantly higher rates of progress than machining operations. 68 (4) As to the newness or novelty hypothesis the findings are contradictory. According to Crawford the rate of progress is an increasing function of the complexity of the job and of the lack of experience of the worker. Schulz and Conway agree with Crawford when they state that the degree of similarity of a machine to a predecessor has a significant effect on the rate of progress; the lggg similarity, the greater the rate of progress. They also observed that the greater complexity, the less the rate of progress. Nevertheless, Alchian and Hirsch found in diverse settings that the greater the similarity of a product to a predecessor, the greater the rate of progress experienced. (5) There existszistrong correlation between the paramg ters of the startup model among startups that oc- curred in a given production facility (Baloff) and among startups that occurred in different facilities (Asher). (6) Plateaux predictability continues to be a contro- Versial issue. CHAPTER III MANUFACTURING PROGRESS FUNCTIONS: A MATHEMATICAL EXPOSITION The interested reader of the literature on manufactug ing progress functions will have certainly noticed that the field lacks uniformity as to mathematical notation and more precise definition of the variables involved. A number of theoretical results are stated and used without formal math ematical demonstration. Assumptions are often implicit in the derivation of important results. In spite of being discrete, the manufacturing progress function may be advantageously treated as a continuous func- tion under certain conditions. The consequent simplification achieved in the final formulas and calculations using the progress function is worthwhile. Nevertheless,these features have been largely neglected in the literature. Such deficiep cies and others that will be pointed out in the course of this chapter have led to a state of confusion in the design, interpretation and evaluation of related empirical research. In the present chapter the mathematical treatment of Progress functions will be rewritten. The systematic exposi- tion here proposed is probably novel in the literature. 69 70 FOUR TYPES OF PROGRESS FUNCTIONS There are at least four types of progress functions,al though they are mathematically related to one another. All four can be expressed as power functions. They are similar in form but have different meaning. The following notations, terminology and definitions will be used in this dissertatflxi Type 1: The Unit Progress Function The functional relationship specified for the unit progress function is: y = ax'b (3.1) where x = the cumulative unit of production y = the direct-labor hours required to produce that xth unit in cumulative production 3 and b = parameters; a>0, Ogbgl Interpretation of Parameters a and b.‘ Parameter i represents the direct labor hours required to produce the initial unit of production: for x = l, y = a(l)'b = a. Param eter 2.13 dependent upon the rate of progress. Geometrically, it is the slope of the progress line, as already mentioned in Chapter 2 (p.12). Another interpretation is suggested by the concept of elasticity of I function. The elasticity of X at the point g is given by: (3.2) and Replacing dz and E in (3.2) by their equivalents already ob- dx y tained, it follows that Ex - (3.3) Thus, parameter b_may be called the progress e1asticity,i.e., the ratio of an infinitely small relative change in the direct labor requirement associated with a correspondingly small relative change in cumulative output. For example, in the "eighty per cent curve" parameter b is 0.32, i.e., a l per cent increase in cumulative output is associated with a 0.32 per cent decline in direct labor requirement.Recalling that the rate of progress has been defined as the complement to one of the "slope", in the case of the"eighty per cent curve" the rate of progress is (l — 0.80) = 0.20 Mei but 1 n ma >1 ($33.). ‘4”, J.“ u 72 Therefore, the rate of progress corresponding to a progress elasticity or parameter b’of 0.32 is about 0.20. Domain and Range of y. - Usually (but not always) §_is a positive integer. In some instances, however, 5 may repre- sent a continuous variable.2 For x = 0, the function is not defined. Thus, in general, the domain X of the unit progress function y is a subset of the positive reals. Usually, the domain X of y is a subset of the set of positive integers. 3 The range set Y of y is a set of positive real numbers. The function y is the set of ordered pairs (x,y) where y = y(x) = ax’b. These specifications may be more compactly expressed by using set theory notation. Thus, generally X = Dom y = {x : xeR+} but usually X = Dom y = {x : xeN} where R+= the set of positive reals N = the set of positive integers: 1,2,3,... Also Y(X)= Ran y= {y:y=ax'b, xeR+(or EN), 552+, beI}C'R+ and y = {(x, y(x)) : xeX} Where I = the unit interval of real numbers. 73 Type 2: The Cumulative Average Progress Function The functional relationship specified for the cumula- tive average progress function is the following: -b y = ax (3.4) where y = the cumulative average direct labor hours per unit x = the cumulative number of units produced 3 and _b = parameters; a>0, 0_<_b_<_l Meaning of a, b and y, Parameters g and b have the same meaning as in the case of the unit progress function.As to the meaning of y, assume a table is available containing a series of values of 5 and the corresponding direct labor hours input per unit, y, for each g: 1 X2. . .Xi. . .Xn y[y1 y2...yi...yn xlx The cumulative average direct labor hours per unit up to and including unit xi is defined as follows: y. 3 i- y. , i = l,2,...,n (3.5) 1 xij 1 J "raw- Equation (3.4) means that the hyperbolic rule of correspon- dence is now between the set of xis and the set of yis where the yis are calculated according to (3.5). . ‘4' ,‘—\ (L) 74 Domain and Range of y > Using set theory notation: X = Dom y = {x : xeR+} (in general) or X = Dom y = {x :xeN} (more usually) Also : y = ax ,xeR+(or 5N), aeR+,beI}C R+ 7(X) = Ran y = {y y = {(x, y(x)) : xeX} where the ys have the meaning given by (3.5) Type 3: The Cumulative Total Progress Function The cumulative total progress function is expressed by: yT = axB (3.6) where yT = cumulative total direct labor hours x =the cumulative number of units produced _a_ and B = parameters; a>0, 05B_<_l Meaning of a, B, and yT. Again, parameter E repre- sents the direct labor hours required to produce the initial unit of production. Parameter B may be seen as the elasticity 0f yT at the point g, As to the meaning of yT, assuming as before that a table of values of g and y is available, the cumulative total direct labor hours expended in producing the first xi units is given by: C.» ‘A MH- '~< i = l,2,...,n (3.7) Equation (3.6) signifies that the rule of association is now between the set of xis and the set of yT 3 calculated i according to (3.7). Domain and Range of yT. Using set theory notation: X = Dom YT = {x : xeR+} (in general) or X = Dom yT = {x : xeN} (more often) Also - = . = B YT(X) Ran yT {yT.yT ax ,xeR+(or eN),a€R+,BeI} C R+ and YT = {(X, YT(X)) : xeX} where the yTs have the meaning given by (3.7). Type 4: The Lot Average Progress Function The lot average progress function is expressed by: “ ’b (3 8) = ax . yL where y: = lot average direct labor hours per unit x =the cumulative number of units produced a and b = parameters; a>0 , Ogbgl 76 Meaning of a, b, and y:. Parameter g represents the direct labor hours required to produce the initial unit of production. Parameter b is the elasticity of y: at the point E- The meaning of y: may be approached as follows. Let xk = the counting from the first unit produced up to and including the last unit of lot k, k = l,2,...,m. Similarly, xk_1 = the number of units from the first unit produced up to and including the last unit of lot (k-l). Therefore xk - xk-l = number of units in lot k. The lot average direct labor hours per unit considering lot}; is defined as follows: yL = , k = l,2,...,n1 (3.9) k xk-xk-l In equation (3.8), the rule of correspondence is now between the set of xks and the set of y 3 calculated according to (3.9). :a 310' ave I «r 77 Domain and Range of y:. Again, employing set theory notation: X = Dom y: = {x : xeR+} (in general) or X = Dom y: = {x : xeN} (more frequently) Also - ‘ _ _ _ _ . = -b YL(X)—Ran —{y .y ax ,xeR+(or eNlaeR+,beI} C R+ ‘4 = {(x,yi(x)) : xeX} where the yi's have the meaning given by (3.9). Fitting the Progress Function to Empirical Data . The crucial problem has been the conformity of the forementioned functional relationships to empirical reality. It is worth mentioning that several other forms have been considered in the literature of progress functions.4 However, the power function continues to be universally employed by the research ers in the field. The preference for the power function may ‘be justified on the following grounds: (1) Adequate fitting to the available data as produced by the firms involved, and (2) simplicity of utilization, particularly when in the form 10f double-logarithmic graph. In the following section it will be shown how the four types of progress functions previously described are mathematically related to one another. 78 FUNDAMENTAL PROBLEMS Statement of Fundamental Problems Almost always progress function users have faced the following four basic problems: Problem I. Given y = y (x) , determine: YT = yT(x) . y = y(x), and yL = yL(x) Problem II. Given y = y(x), determine: YT = YT(X). y = y(X). and yL = yL(X) Problem III. Given yT = yT(x), determine: F = §(X). y y(X). and 5 = §L(X) L Problem IV. Given y: yL(x), determine: yT = yT(X). F = §(X), and Y = y(X). Whenever the expression "gi_vgp the function. . . is used in this chapter, it signifies that the focused function can be statistically fitted to the empirical data and moreover, that the chosen function is the one that yields the best fitting of the four types of progress functions already 79 defined. From such point on the other three progress func- tions may be determined through mathematical analysis, as follows. Solution of Problem I (a) Given the cumulative average progress function y = y(x), the cumulative total progress function may be determined by using definition equation (3.5): yT(x) = §(x) - x (3.10) In case the discrete function y = y(x) is approxi- ax'b, it follows from (3.10) that: mated by y l-b ax , x = 1,2,... (3.11) yT (X) (b) The unit progress function will be determined by subtracting the cumulative total hours consumed in the production of the first (x-l) units from the cumulative total hours consumed in the production of the first 5 units. The difference is exactly am: the hours consumed in producing unit 5 alone: = - -l .12 y(X) YT(X) yT(x ) (3 ) or according to (3.11) and (3.12): y(x) = a [él-b - (x-l)1-€] ,x=l,2,... (3.13) 80 (c) The lot average progress function is easily deter- ‘mined by adopting the same notation of the previous section. Therefore, according to equations (3.9) and (3.11): ‘4 or l-b l-b a(xk - xk_1) yL = , k=l,2,...,m,x =0 (3.UD k xk-xk-l O Using equation (3.14) and given the number of units in each lot k, k=l,2,...,m, it is possible to calculate a table Lk termin I = _ . e YL YL(X) of values of as a function of xk and x and thus to d9 k-l Using the Continuity Assumption to Approximate Solu- tions . As it was previously noted, progress functions are often discrete. Nevertheless it is viable to approximate so- lutions by assuming continuity of the progress function in the interval of interest. Take, for example equation (3.13). For values of g'not very close to the first units of produg tion: NIH y(x) a fox y(x) dx (3.15) 81 Equation (3.15) follows from the definition of the av- erage or mean value of function y = y(x) over the interval from zero to x. It is assumed that y(x) is continuous over the interval of interest.5 Since y = y(x) is being approxi- mated by y = ax-b, it follows from (3.15) that X _ l’b f y(x) dx 5 y(x)-x = ax (3.16) 0 Derivation of (3.16) with respect to 5 yields: b a (1-b)x- (3-17) Ill y(X) Equation (3.16) is the same as (3.11). Recall that equation (3.11) was derived by assuming that the discrete function y = y(x) could be approximated by y = ax'b. Calculation of the unit progress function through (3.17) is evidently faster and simpler than through the exact equation (3.13) even if machine computation is considered. Since §'= y(x) is given, it suffices to multiply the ye by (l-b) in order to obtain the ys. It is worth mentioning that the function: f(1og x) = log a + log(1-b) - b log x is asymptote of F (log x) = log {a [él-b - (x—1)1-€]} 82 This result is used very often in the literature but no formal proof is offered except the recourse to geometrical intuition. In Appendix B this author states it as a theorem and contributes a formal mathematical demonstration. The ra- tionale for approximating equation (3.13) by equation (3.17) (for values of 5 not close to the first units) stems from this theorem. Solution of Problem II (a) Given the unit progress function y = y(x), the cumg lative total direct labor hours up to and including unit g is given by definition (3.7): yT(x) 3 z y(x) x = 1,2,... (3.18) x In case the discrete function y = y(x) is approxi- mated by y = ax-b, then: yT(x)= Z ax-b= a x-b, x= 1,2,... (3.19) )3 x x (b) The cumulative average progress function is deter- mined through definition (3.5) and equation (3.18): y (X) £34") T = -—-———— (3.20) X 370:) = Therefore, in case y=y(x) is approximated by y=ax-b, the cumulative average function is given by: 83 -b y(x) =3 x , x = 1,2,... (3.21) X x (c) In order to determine the lot average progress function, given the unit progress function, let: xk the counting from the first unit produced up to and including the last unit of lot 5, k=l,2,...,m, xo=0. xk-l = the counting from the first unit produced up to and including the last unit of lot (k-l). In case the discrete function y=y(x) is approxi- mated by y=ax-b, equation (3.19) yields: and The total direct labor hours expended in lot k.is obtained by subtracting the last equation from the first one: yT = x“b - 23 x ) (3.22) k "k xk-l _b a(2 l 84 (xk_l+j) , k=l,2,...,m,x0=0 (3.23) The lot average direct labor hours for lot k_wi11 be given by: _ -b a . y = -——————- Z (xk +3) (3.24) Lk xk xk—l J=1 1 Given the number of units in each lot §,k=l,2,...mr it is possible to calculate a table of values of yLk as a function of xk and xk-l through equation (3.24) and thus to determine yi= yi(x). Approximating the Summation Formulas by Integrals. The formulas involving summations may be approximated by improper integrals. Take, for example, formula (3.19): x _ x _ -b x b= a lim f x b = 1%E-x1 (3.25) Y (X) s a f T 0 x1+0 x1 Using definition (3.5) and the approximation in (3.25% the cumulative average progress function given by equation (3.21) may be expressed as: y (X) T a -b —— x (3.26) _ A y(X) — l-b ~ - - 85 Also, it follows from equation (3.25) that: l-b Tk(X )~ _I_— xk and ~ a x1-b yT(xk-l) - 1 xk_1 Thus, l-b _ __ YT“? ' yT(-"1<1 _a("1< YL - ’ k xk xk- 1 Solution of Problem III (l-b)(xk-xk_1) (3.27) This problem is trivial once the solution to problem I is presented. (a) Given the cumulative total progress function, yT = yT(x), the cumulative average progress func- tion is merely: YT(X) lll> F (X) X In case YT yT(x) is approximated by y (3.28) ‘ ax the T -' 9 cumulative average progress function will be of the form: y(x) = ax _ , x=l,2,... (3.29) (b) The unit progress function may be obtained as in Problem I: 86 Y(X) = YT(X) - YT(x-1) Given that yT= yT(x) is of the form yT = axB , y(x) = a £43 - (x-1)B:] ,x=l,2,... (3.30) (c) The lot average progress function is determined by the same method already explained in the case of Problem I. The resulting expression is: B B _ 8(Xk - Xk_1) Y = , k=l,2,...,m, x = O (3.31) Lk xk xk-l Solution of Problem IV (a) Given the lot average progress function §i=yi(x), the total direct labor hours consumed by the manu- facturing of lot k is given by: ka= yLk(xk - xk_1) , k=l,2,...,m, x =0 (3.32) The cumulative total direct labor hours since the inception of production up to and including unit xk (the last of lot k) is, therefore: k = 2 — .- , k=l,2,..., , =0 3.33 YT(xk) j=1 ij(xJ xj_1) m x0 ( ) 87 In case §L= yi(x) is being approximated by yi=ax'b, the cumulative total direct labor hours from unit number one up to and including unit x is,according k to (3.33): k -b yT(xk)— ajil xj (xj-Xj-l)’ k=l,2,...,m, xo=0 (3.34) (b) The cumulative average direct labor hours per unit up to xk will be, by definition: y(X) — A y(xk)=-I—-13— (3.35) xk If y: = yi(x) is being approximated by §L= ax-b, then, according to (3.34) and (3.35): _()=-§-1§x-b(-x )k=12 mx=0 (336) yxk x = o x. ’- , ’ ”"’ ’ O ' k j 1 J J J 1 (c) Given the lot average progress function yi=yi(x), the unit progress function cannot be exactly deter- mined. However, an assumption can be made, i.e., that the lot average direct labor hours considering lot k'is approximately equal to the lot average direct labor hours considering lot 5 deleted by its last unit xk. Symbolically, 88 YT YT - y(xk) _ A g yL = -—-:%3——— ' E 1 _ (3.37) k xk xk-l Xk xk-l If (3.37) holds, then: y(xk) a yLk (3.38) i.e., the unit progress function can be approxi- mated by the lot average progress function. An al- ternative way of checking the validity of (3.38), given the same assumption (3.37) is as follows. The cumulative total direct labor hours up to and including unit xk is, according to (3.33): k y (x ) = E y (x - x. ) = T k j=1 Lj J J l k-l _ _ = 2 ,- , + x -x 3.39 j=1 YLj(xJ XJ-1) yLk( k k_1) ( ) In view of (3.37), the cumulative total direct labor hours up to and including unit (xk - 1) may be expressed as follows: k-l YT(xk- 1) s jil §Lj z axk (3.41) Note.- : Problem IV as well as item (c) of Problems I, II, and III are not formally treated in the literature. The unit progress function and the lot average progress function are taken as the same model. The approximation and the assunp tion behind it are not explained. The confusion may have its origin in the fact that the unit progress function is rarely encountered in a real world situation. Labor expenditure is typically recorded on a monthly, as opposed to a per-unit basis. As a result, direct labor hours data are normally cal culated and reported in relation to standard accounting time periods, yielding average direct labor hours per unit figures for the "lot" of product produced during the accounting period. Also, cumulative output statistics (x) indicate the total output of the product (from inception of manufacture) that is achieved at thg gag of the accounting period. Thus, What exists in practice is the lot average function §L=yi(x) as previously defined, not the unit function y = y (x). 90 Nevertheless, in the literature the lot average function is designated by the term "unit function"... PARAMETER CALCULATION Application of the progress function to practical prob lems involves two requirements: (1) It must be known which type of progress function best fits the empirical data. In practice the cumg lative average progress function and the lot aver- age progress function are very popular .. In some special situations where data is available in a per unit basis the unit progress function may also be considered. (2) Parameters g and b_must be known or somehow calcu- lated so that the progress function can be applied. In this section it is assumed that the cumulative ave; age progress function (type 2) is the best fitted to the available empirical data. Once given the type of progress function there exist two general classes of problems involy ing parameter calculation: (A) Given a point in the progress curve and the slope of the progress line, determine the progress func- tion. 91 (B) Given two points in the progress curve, determine the progress function. Class (A) involves solely parameter E determination since parameter b (the slope of the progress line) is given. In class (B) both parameters must be calculated. Each class contains four problems. Their statements and respective solutions will be the subject of this section. Statement of Problem Al Given a point in the cumulative average progress curve, (xi, y(xi)) and the slope of the progress line (parameter b), determine the cumulative average progress function y = y(x). Solution of Problem A1 Since, by assumption, y = ax'b, one must have: -b ax. 1 F (xi) 3" (xi) x: (3.42) O O 8 Parameter b’is given and parameter 3 can be calculated by (3.42). Thus, problem Al is solved, i.e., I = ax'b = §(xi) x‘i’ x'b (3.43) 92 Statement of Problem A2 Given a point in the cumulative total progress curve, (xi, yT(xi)), and parameter b, determine the cumulative ave; age progress function y = y(x). Solution of Problem A2 From equation (3.11): l-b yT (xi) " axi - y (X.) _ T i a — ——I:b—- (3.44) x. 1 Since b'is known and E can be calculated by (3.44), problem A2 is solved. The cumulative average progress func- tion will be given by: y (x.) _ -b T i -b = = -————— 3.45 y ax 1-b x ( ) i X Statement of Problem A3 Given a point in the unit progress curve, (xi, y(xi)) and parameter b, determine the cumulative average progress function y = y(x). 93 Solution of Problem A3 According to equation (3.13): _ 1-b Y(xi)=aEc:b-(xi-l)] .'. a = (3.46) Again, since b is known and 3 can be calculated through (3.46), problem A3 is solved. The cumulative average progress function will be given by: .V = ax = x (3.47) Statement of Problem A4 Given a point in the lot average progress curve, (Xk, §L(xk)) and parameter b, determine the cumulative aver- age progress function y = y(x). Solution of Problem A4 One possible solution is to use approximation (3.36), FL (Xk) E y(xk) 94 In this case, problem A4 is reduced to problem A3 already solved. If the number of units in lot k is known, say, nk, than equation (3.14) may be used to determine parameter 3. Since xk_1 = xk ‘ nk’ it follows from (3.14): a = 1-b l-b (3'48) xk Wham) Thus, the cumulative average progress function will be ex- pressed by: ? nk y = ax"b = l-b Lk 1-b x'b (3.49) - (xk - nk) Statement of Problem Bl Given two points in the cumulative average progress curve, (xi, y(xi)) and (xj, y(x,)), determine the cumulative average progress function y y(x). Solution of Problem B1 Since, by assumption, y = ax b, one must have: T (Xi) = ax;b (3.50) and 95 -b . (3.51) J — x. = ax y ( J) Dividing (3.50) by (3.51), taking logarithms and solving for 2, yields: log [mp/571x33] b = (3.52) log (xj/xi) After calculating b, parameter p may be calculated from (3.5» or from (3.51). Therefore, using (3.50): — b a = y(X.) X. (3'53) 1 1 Once parameters 2 and g are calculated, problem B1 is solved. The cumulative average progress function will be given by: where b and 3 are calculated through equations (3.52) and (3.53), respectively. Statement of Problem B2 Given two points in the cumulative total progress curve, (xi, yT(xi)) and (xj, yT(xj)), determine the cumulative ave; age progress function y = y(x). 96 Solution of Problem BZ According to equation (3.11): l-b y (X,) = aX, (3.54) T 1 1 and l-b x. = a 3.55 YT < J> xj < > Dividing (3.54) by (3.55), applying logarithms and solving for 2, yields: log [:yT/yTB The cumulative average progress function will be given by: f = ax‘b = k k x3 ' 1 (3.82) 103 * where B is calculated through iteration formula (3.72) with A, C, D, E, and F given by (3.79). SUMMARY The field of manufacturing progress functions lacks notation uniformity, precise definition of the variables and functional relationships involved, and formal proofs of impq; tant results. The fact that the progress function may be advanta- geously treated as a continuous function so as to simplify final formulas and speed up solutions has been largely ne- glected in the literature. Instead, formidable formulas that are given to computers to digest are preferred in the name of exactness... In this chapteréuloriginal mathematical exposition of the progress function is offered. Initially, four types of progress function are identified. Functional relationships for the four types are clearly and compactly defined with recourse to set theory notation. Parameters g and b are care- fully explained and suggestively interpreted. In a second section, four fundamental problems which I users might have faced consciously or unconsciously, are fo; mally stated and solved, at times by more than one method. Finally, parameter calculation problems are classified and solved by exact or approximate formulas. CHAPTER IV QUADRATURE AND SUMMATION OF PROGRESS FUNCTIONS This chapter represents a continuation of the mathema; ical exposition on progress functions initiated with Chapter III. Two related topics of practical relevance are now ap- proached: the integration of progress functions and the de- batable problem of their aggregation.Original approximations are proposed for both problems. QUADRATURE OF PROGRESS FUNCTIONS Cumulative Total Hours Calculation Let the manufacturing progress function be expressed as a unit progress function: y = ax-b (4.1) Also, let (xu, yu) be the point in the progress curve where a plateau begins (Figure 4). This point has already been de- fined in Chapter II (page 39 ). For the moment it is assumed that it can be practically determined. 104 105 Mfg.Hrs/Unit ‘4 c: XI 111 l Cumulative Units of Production FIGURE 4 Progress Curve Ultimate Point (xu,yu) and Manufacturing Progress Function Hours. Recall that with equation (4.1) holding for the unit curve, the exact expression for the cumulative total hours is given by: y = a 2 x (4.2) x Approximation Methods . (a) An approximation method that eliminates calculation of every unit value in equation (4.2) was suggested in a study prepared by Boeing Airplane Company, already mentioned in Chapter II (page 20 , equation 2.7). Essentially, the integral is taken of equation (4.1) with respect to ; between the limits 0.5 and (xu + 0.5) so as 106 to improve the approximation. Thus: + y ~ 7X“ 0.sax_b dx = i (x +0 5)1'b 0 51'b (4 3) T - 0.5 l-b u . . .. (b) However, a simpler approximation was also suggested in Chapter III. From equation (3.25) it follows that a 1-b YT(xu) - 1- xu (4.4) for xu not very close to the first units in the series. But, according to equation (4.1): _ b a — yuxu (4.5) Therefore, from (4.4) and (4.5): X Y s u u x : [.6 1T (Xu) l-b (+ ) where yT(xu) does not depend on parameter 3. The same reasoning might be applied to equation (4.3). Hence, from (4.3) and (4.5), it follows that: b x y _ yT(x ) 5 u u [Exu+0.5)l-b - 0.51 g] (4.7) u l-b 107 (c) A third approach to be proposed herein is suggested by l Euler-MacLaurin summation formula: X n 1 1 82 h . . :Of(xi)= hfx: f(x)dx+§ [f(x0)+ f(xrfl +—2'_—[:f (xg- f (x0)] + 3 B4 h + 4: E“ (xn) - fm(x0):] + ...+ 20-3 B h ~ _ + 216.2 [f(Zp—3) (b) _ f(21> 3) (3)] (2p-2)! 20 B h~ + nu —2}’———— (4.8) (29)! Formula (4.8) is useful for finding the approximate sum of any number of consecutive values of a function when these values are given for equidistant values of x, provided the integral L§n(x)dx can be easily evaluated. In this formula ‘0 h is the distance between the equidistant values of ;, so that n11= xn - xO . The last term is a remainder where u designates an average value of f(2p)(x) between x0 and xn .The B's are Bernoulli numbers. Recall that these are the numbers Bl’BZ""’Bn’ defined by the expansion of the following generating function: x =]_+—I—!-+-—2T-—+...+T+... (4.9) 108 convergent provided that [x] < 2 . Also, recall from the related theory that: and B The B's with even indices have alternate signs and the following values: _ _5_ = _ 691 = Z ___ 3617 B10 66’ BIZ 2730’ 314 6’ B16 510’ = 43867 B = _ 174611 B = 854513 13 798 ’ 20 330 ’ 22 138 ’ B Replacing the B's in (4.8) for their values, yields: n 1 X“ 1 h , , iEof(xi)= h f f(x)dx + 7 f(x0)+ f(xn) + I2 f (xn)- f (x0) 3 5 h h ‘ 776 E... (Kn)- f'" “‘0’} 30240 Evan)— 970(0)] 7 h vii vii - —-———-— f x - f x - R (4.10 1209600 I: ( n) ( 0)] ) 109 The Inherent Error in Euler-MacLaurin Formula . In (4.10) the terms on the right side, beginning with (h/12)[f'(xn) - f'(xOZ], form an asymptotic series. In comput ing with such a series it is important to know what term to stop with in order to get the most accurate result. One get the most accurate result by stopping with the term just be- fore the smallest,since according to C.V.L. Charlier,in stopping with any term in Euler-MacLaurin' formula the error committed is less than twice the first neglected term. It can also be shown that the first two terms of Euler-MacLaurin formula 4 will give a more accurate result than Simpson's Rule. By taking the first three terms in formula (4.10), the third formula for approximating equation (4.2) can be derived as follows: =a :u x-bc'aijéuf(x)dx4-ljf(l)+ f(x Z]+-l;[f'(x )- f'(ffl} YT 1 = l E’ ‘ u 12 n (4.11) b x 'b 1 1 b Since, f(x) = x" ,7 u x' dx = —-(x ' - 1), f(1)= 1, 1 l-b u f(x ) = x'b, f'(x) = - bx-(b+l), f'(x ) = - b x-(b+l), and u U u u f'(l) = - b, it follows from (4.11) that: .. _L 1-b_ l -b _b_ _ -(b+1) YT(xn) = a [l-b (Xu 1) + 2(1+xu ) + 12 (l x ) .13) 110 or from (4.5): y (x ) 5y xb [—_1:— xi'b-l)+%— (1+x11b)+j% (l-x;(b+l)% (4.14) Manufacturing Progress Function Hours Calculation In Chapter II the term "MPF hours" was defined as theme hours over and above the estimated hours which are caused by the introduction of a new unit into a manufacturing system. The MPF hours or the direct labor hours associated with the 'manufacturing progress function can be measured by the shaded area in Fig.4. Knowledge of the MPF hours may be of extreme importance to management in deciding about the implementathn1 onf a new product or a major change in existing products.The practical development of such matters will be delayed until a later chapter. In the following paragraphs four methods for calculating the MPF hours are proposed and assessed. Exact Method. An obvious approach is suggested by equation (4.2). Noting that the shaded area in Figure 4 is the difference between the total area under the progress curve and the rectangular area x yu, and also using equation u (4.1), the MPF hours consumed by units number 1 up to and including unit xu can be exactly determined as follows: MPF Hours II 0) = a (z: x'b - xl'b) (4.15) 1 u Also, according to (4.5): ‘L‘! _ b xu _b MPF ...-ours - yuxu 2i x - xuyu 1. x“ -b = xuyu ( l-b Z x — l) (4.16) xu 1 Note that formula (4.16) does not require the knowledge of parameter E. Formulas (4.15) and (4.16) are better suited for machine computation. Tables can be programmed and devel- oped on a digital computer. Approximate Methods. Equations (4.3), (4.4) and (4.13) suggest three possible approximations to the problem of calculating the MPF hours. Again, subtraction of the rec--~ tangular area xuyu from the total area under the progress curve,and equation (4.1) yield the following results: (a) Using equation (4.3) l-b l-b MPF Hours 3 I%b [Exu+0.5) ~ 0.5 :] - xuyu = a{'f}jg [(1H1+0.5)1-b - 0.514)] - xi-b} (4.17) Also, according to (4.5): l-b -b (xu+ 0.5) - 0.51 J - 1 l-b (l-b) xu (4.18) MPF Hours 5 x y [: Uu 112 (b) Using equation (4.4) ‘ ~ _;;_ l-b _ ab l-b MPF Hours l-b xu - xuyu I:— xu (4.19) Also, from (4.5): A MPF Hours a 14:1 xl'b - xuyu b = 1:71; am. (410) Equations (4.19) and (4.20) are much simpler than (4.17) and (4.18) and are well suited for manual calcula- tion. (c) Using equation (4.13) . [T1— (.13-b- 1>+;<1+x; b) + llz MPF Hours -b b - I2 (1 - xu(b+l)% ' Xuyu l l-b l -b = a [%:g (xu — l) + E (1+xu ) + j; -(b+l) l-b 12 (l - xu ) - xu 7] (4.21) or from (4.5): l _ MPF Hours 5 xuyuy{ {Eb[%:g'(x: b-1)+ i‘bef%9 + x x u U b 1 I2 (1 - b+l{] - l } (4.22) u 113 Equations (4.21) and (4.22) derived from Euler- -MacLaurin summation formula are the most accurate of the three proposed approximations. They can be easily handled by a pocket calculator. Accuracy of the Proposed Formulas In order to demonstrate the accuracy of formulas (4.3), (4.4), and (4.13) the cumulative total hours values were machine computed for xu = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 10, 20, 30, 40, 50, 100, 200, 300, 400, 500, and. 999 using the exact formula (4.2) and also calculated with a HP-25 Scientific Programma- ble Pocket Calculator through the approximation formulas. In all cases parameter §_was taken as 100 hours. Table 4.1 was developed for b = 0.152003 (90% progress curve). The per- cent deviations from the exact values are also shown in the referred table. Such results were plotted on semi-log graph (Figure 5). THE AGGREGATION PROBLEM Consider the sum of two progress functions given by: y1 = alx-b1 and. -b2 y2 = 82x The sum is - -b1 -b2 (4.23) y1 + y2 = alx + azx EXACT AND APPROXIMATE CUMULATIVE TOTAL 114 TABLE 4.1 HOURS; a = 100, b = 0.152003 (90% curve) Formula Formula % Formula % Formula % xu (4.2) (4.3) dev. (4.4) dev. (4.13) dev. 1 100.000000 100.800810 0.801 117.920906 17.9 100.000000 0 2 190-000000 190.968570 0.510 212.260916 11.7 190.036653 0.0193 3 270.620600 275.658038 0o378 299.366015 9.01 270.661171 0.0108 0 355.620600 356.695583 0.302 382.076873 7.00 355.662119 0.0117 5 033.919300 035.017196 0.253 061.668002 6.13 033.961129 0.0096 10 799.007900 800.592303 0.103 831.003177 3.95 799,090071 0.0053 20 1060.776000 1061.903251 0.080 1095.805815 2.00 1060,818365 0.0029 30 2072.689300 2073.863996 0.057 2109.599805 1.78 2072.731906 0.0021 00 2650.271300 2655.009680 0.000 2692.050601 1.00 2650.310187 0.0016 50 3210.195500 32150376092 0.037 3253.322750 1.22 3210.238600 0.0013 100 5810.101800 5815.287300 0.020 5855.981338 0.720 5810.106067 0.0008 200 10096.006000 10097.59535 0.011 10500.76709 0.023 10096.05236 0.0000 300 10820-002800 10821.59509 0.008 10866.10092 0.308 10820.05157 0.0003 000 18926.783000 18927.97795 0.006 18973.38198 0.206 18926.83017 0.0003 500 22878.510500 22879.70727 0.005 22925.78159 0-207 22878-56330 0-0002 999 01182.189600 01183.39816 0.003 01231.01311 0.120 01182.25397 0.0002 115 100 ~~3——- _ --2»——~—~-—3-—-—- 4- 5 s 1 7,, ~ .3 - -~9 - ~10 -7.- q. .._.T.._ x (cumulative units) ‘ FIGURES - EXACT AND APPROXIMATE CUMULATIVE wTOTAL _ .1, HQURS vs. CUMULATIVE PRODUCTION a = 100, b= 0.152003 (90% CURVE)“ 116 A log-log plot of (y1 + yz) versus ; is a convex curve whose shape depends upon parameters (a1, a2, b1, b2). The plot will be linear if and only if bl = b2 = b -b yl + y2 = (a1 + 82) X (4~24) Strictly speaking, if the model is assumed to hold for two separate portions of a task it cannot also be assumed to hold for their sum unless the separate curves have equal slopes - which will not in general be the case. Several authors contend that this fact precludes the use of the linear model for operations, departments, sections and total of the same project.5 Notwithstanding, it is the purpose of this section to show that it is theoretically correct and even desirable in practical work to approximate the sum of m_progress functions of different parameters by a progress function of the same functional form as the addend functions. Statement of the Problem Given m progress functions determine a function of the form such that Y Ill ":43 <1 117 Solution of the Aggregation Problem Expressing a Progress Function as a Power Series. The result known as Taylor's series may be posed as follows: y(x)=y(c)+ 1%(f:l(x—c)+ iii—(Ig- (x-c)2+. . .+ 1531;92- (x-c)n+. . . n (4.25) Taylor's series may be used for the expansion of any given function y(x) in a power series in (x-c), provided the expansion exists . For a function to admit of a Taylor's series expansion in powers of (x-c), it is necessary that the function be finite and possess finite derivatives of all orders at x = c. The series in the right member of (4.25) will have a sum equal to y(x) whenever the series converges. -b Let y(x) = ax . Therefore, expanding y(x) into Taylor's series yields: y(x) = ax-b y'(x) = -abx-(b+l) y"(x) = ab(b+l) x-(b+2) y'"(x) = -ab(b+l)(b+2) x‘(b+3) -(b+n) y(n)(x) = (-1)n ab(b+l)(b+2)...(b+n-l)x , n=l,2,3,... or equivalently n a(b-l)!b(b+l)(b+2)...(b+n-l) X-(b+n) (b-l)! y“) (x) = <-1> 118 n a(b+n-l)! x-(b+n) =(-1> (H)! , “0,1,2”. Also Y(c) = ac-b y'(¢) = -abc’(b+1) y"(c) = ab(b+l) c‘(b+2) Y'"(C) = -ab(b+1)(b+2) c'(b+3) n a(b+n-l)! c-(b+n) 3"“) (c) = <-1> (b-l)! . n = 0,1,2.... By substituting these values in equation (4.25), it follows that: —b -b abc c .— -(b+l) -(b+2) y=ax =a (x—c)+ab(b+l)C 1! 2’ (x-C) - n a(b+n-l)! C-(b+n) (x-c n I1!(b-l)! ) 4' '°' + (-1) (_l)n a(b+n-1)! C-(b+n) 0 n!(b_1)! (x-c)n (4.26) ll "v18 i Existence of the Expansion. In order to prove that the expansion in (4.26) exists, it suffices to prove that lim Rn = 0 n+oo where Rn is the remainder term of the expansion. It is given by: (n) Rn = Y [E :19 (x'cij (x-c)n, 0<0<1 (4.27) 119 Since y(n)(x) = (-1)n ab(b+l)...(b+n-1)x-(b+n),n=l,2, it follows that: y(n)[§+6(x-CX]=(-l)n ab(b+l)...(b+n-l)[§+e(x-CX]-(b+n) Hence, from (4.27): n R =(_1)n ab(b+l)(b+2)...(b+:;l) . (XQ?) (4.28) n [E + 6 (x - CZ] n But |y(n) (x)! decreases with x,and 0 < 0 < 1. Thus: NOE: + e(x-c)jl < y‘n)N, put n = N + k. Then, Since Effie '—"-?1- 63—8 (rm?) . it follows that N |(X'C2n| < (X'C) . _1_ n! N! 2k 120 And for n2>N, N N [Rn] §§iili§i' c"b+“’n Then = _ n+1 a (b+n)! _(b+n+1) - n+1 ‘1 +1 ( 1) (n+l)l(b-l)! c (x C) And after the necessary simplifications l un+ll_ lb+nc x-c x-c _'n+bc 121 X-C <1 for convergence (4.31) u ' n+1 = l. It follows from (4.31) that the interval of convergence is 0 < x < 2c (4.32) At the end points of the interval of convergence, the simple ratio test can never be effective. Convergence or divergence will have to be tested by other criteria. At the end point x = 2c the series has: n a(b+n-l)! _ un = (‘1) nl(b-l)1 C (b+n) C“ n a(n+l)(n+2)...(n+b—l) cb(b-l)! = (-1) (4.33) Since the series has alternate signs and the nth term in (4.33) numerically decreasestx>zero as 2 becomes infinite the series is convergent at x = 2c. To see this: lim a(n+l)(n+2)...(n+b-l)== .a lim nb-l = O n+w Cb(b-1)! c (b-l)! n+m (recall that Ogbgl in a progress function) At the end point x = O the progress function is not defined. Thus, the Taylor's expansion given by (4.26) is valid for all 5 such that OC (X-C)2 _ l! 2! -(B+n) m -b. _ r1A(B+n-l)!c _ ‘n = J _ +( l) n!(B-1)! (x c) +... jil ajc b b (b +1) -(b1+2) m a. . -(b.+1 111 a, . . C -. [:22 _a_—11c J ](x-c)+£2 J J J2, ](x-c)2-... j=1 .=1 ' + [:f (-1)n j=l - (b.+n) aj(b.+n-l)!c J J n n!(bi-1)! (X-C) +a.. (4.40) If the expansions in (4.40) are truncated after the second term and the method of undetermined coefficients is employed, it follows that: -B m ‘b. Ac = 22 ac 1 (4.41) i=1 J and _ m. -(b.+l) ABc (3+1) = z a.b.c J (4.42) '=1 J J J Solving (4.41) and (4.42) for A and B yields: m -bj Z a.b.c _ j=1 J J B — 'm -b (4.43) 2 a.c J and B A = c D (4.44) 125 where D is the denominator in (4.43) -b. Thus, given y1 = ajx J , aj>0, 03b131, it is possible to find y = Ax'B, (A>O , O129 Moog .Q €555 .. mzonoza BEBE 3% ”5.384% 2.. H95 o HERE Amid: gwumgov x 98 SH o3 on S 2056sz HOSE ZOE—[Eh fig ngomg 9: cow 8: com 08 o8 o8 HE: has: 130 The results in Table 4.2 and Figure 6 show that the approximate aggregate function in (4.48) is quite effective in representing the exact aggregate function after the 40th or 50th unit up to the 1000th unit in the series. If the focus is on the early units of the series it suffices to change the value of g and recalculate the para- meters A and B for a new approximate aggregate function in that interval. For example, assuming that the interval of interest is now x e [1, 20] then 150 x 0.322 350 x 0.152 500 x 0.515 0 322 + 0.152 + 0.515 3:: 10 10 10 _ 139.165507 ' 470.853278 150 + 350 + 500 100‘322 100'I52 100'SIS = 0.295560 and A = C3 - D = 100'295560 x 470.853278 = 929.920021 The aggregate function may be represented by -0.296 y E 930 x (4.49) 131 A second table is calculated by following steps 1-5 previously mentioned (Table 4.3). The results are also plotted on arithmetic graph paper (Figure 7). It is manifest that the approximate aggregate function in (4.49) fairly well represents the exact aggregate function in the interval [1, 20] and even beyond the 20th unit. TABLE 4 . 3 EXACT AND APPROXIMATE AGGREGATE PROGRESS FUNCTION-INTERVAL E1, 20] 3 y 5 Z x 1 Yj 930 x-0.296 dev. 1 1000.000 930.000 7.00 2 784.891 757.492 3.49 3 685.437 671.823 1.99 4 624.346 616.983 1.18 5 581.655 577.548 0.71 10 470.854 470.417 0.093 20 386.039 383.158 0.75 30 345.629 339.825 1.68 40 320.315 312.085 2.57 50 302.362 292.138 3.38 100 254.518 237.948 6.51 _.132_ ., flow . .Q A<>§ .. mZOHHUsz mmmmuomm §§< Magnum Qz< HOSE N. mmDUHm Amuwg o>wumH25ov x 8 2 m .. m N H 1“ 8 a can con 1 6523 3658.4. 8.. Egg com / so 2:. zoEozE mmmmuomm Ba 2. 8m T 82 3.25 A .61: 133 Accuracy in the Quadrature of Approximate Aggregate Functions The main interest of approximate aggregation of prog- ress functions may reside in estimating the total direct labor hours and the MPF hours to be consumed by a prospec- tive manufacturing program where one or several new products are involved. Since this is one of the potential applicatflnns of the manufacturing progress function to be treated in chapter VII no further comments are necessary at this point. However, to show how accurate the integratiOn of the approximate aggregate function isthe following sample checking is carried out. The same data of the previous subsection is assumed. (1) For each given progress function y1(x), y2(x) and y3(x) the g§§§§ total hours expended in the manufacturing of unit 1 up to and including unit 999 are machine computed through formula (4.2). Thus: 999 yT = 150 z x‘0°322= 150 x 158.562733 1 1 23784.40995 999 -0.152 YT = 350 z x = 350 x 411.821896 2 1 144137.6636 999 -0 Slr y = 500 2 x ' ’= 500 x 57.3720489 T3 1 28686.02445 134 (2) The total hours expended in the three products (or actig ities) represented by progress functions y1(x), y2(x) and y3(x) are computed 3 2 YT. = 196608.0981 1 1 (3) Now the approximate aggregate function in (4.48) is used in order to calculate the same total hours consumed by y1(x), y2(x) and y3(x). Since the focused interval is sufficiently large, formula (4.4) may be used: a A 1-B _ 664 0.787 _ y - 1:3 X — 67737 X 999 - 193575.9442 T (4) The per cent deviation of the approximate result obtained in step 3 with respect to the exact result from step 2 is computed: % dev. = 193576 - 196608 X 100% = _ 1.54 % 196608 It may be concluded from step (4) that even using the less accurate formula (4.4) the value of the integral is approximated with reasonable accuracy. Again, considering the interval [1, 20] and going through the same previously mentioned steps, the following results are obtained: 3 20 -0 22 20 _ 20 _ exact total hours= ZyT = 150 Z x '3 +350 2 x O'152+500 Z x 0'5”: 1 i 1 1 1 = 10388.7271 135 From formula (4.4) and equation (4.49): 0.704 a 930 x 20 = 10885.17477 0.704 approximate total hours yT 10885—10389 10389 % dev. x 100% = 4.78% ()1: from formula (4.3) and equation (4.49) = —2§9— 20 50'704 0 50'704 — 10265 1192 YT - 0.704 ( ' - ' ) _ ' % dev. = 10265'10389 x 100% = - 1.19% 10389 CHAPTER V A MODEL OF THE PROGRESS PHENOMENON IN MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES The objectives of the study included the derivation of £1 symbolic-analytic model of the manufacturing progress phe- nomenon. Such a model will be presented in this chapter. This purpose cannot be accomplished without a means of understanding how system adaptation can exist in a manufac- turing concern. It is worthwhile to expend some effort in questioning the causes of, or reasons for, the systematic gains in productivity embodied in the progress curve,however tentative the resulting explanation might be. Although system adaptation can exist in a wide variety of production systems, methodological problems can impose Serious restrictions on a study of the phenomenon. These problems, and their influence on the study, are also dis- cussed in this chapter. A CONCEPT OF MANUFACTURING PROGRESS The manufacturing progress function is essentially an e . mp 1rical concept. There is no rational or deductive proof 1: - hat, can be advanced to support it or the assumptions upon Vol-1 - 10h it is based. While these assumptions may be intuitively 136 A 137 appealing, they must be empirically validated. The three assumptions upon which the MPF is based are: (1) The amount of time required to complete a given task or unit of produc- tion will decrease each successive time the task is under- taken; (2) The rate at which this reduction in unit time will occur will be a decreasing one, and (3) This reduction in ‘unit time will follow a specific predictable pattern. It has been demonstrated in the literature that these Tassumptions are valid for many classes of products and manu- :facturing processes. Moreover, they may serve the purpose of Iaroviding a preliminary characterization of the manufacturing garogress phenomenon. Iféictors in Manufacturing Progress There are several factors which may influence or con- 1:::ribute to manufacturing progress: (1) The production worker, (2) Management, and (3) Staff or supporting personnel. Their C=arogress curve exhibiting plateaux of no improvement followed ‘E33r'sharp drops reflecting sudden management emphasis. Staff and/or Supporting Personnel. It is suggested that a substantial portion of the manufacturing progress will t><3 the result of the efforts of the supporting personnel who in many organizations are listed under the headings of the “’éaitfiious staff functions. It is also suggested that the im- 33:=7<>‘Jements contributed by the staff functions will be more <3"13’ £1 continuing, long-ranging and long-lasting nature and that they will be the significant factor after the initial 1‘€3“Ellfining has been accomplished by the production workers. 53 . QLIQ of the typical contributions from the various staff 139 offices are discussed in the following paragraphs. Tooling. The type of tooling used, the degree of completion or development prior to production and the changes made during production will influence the magnitude of manu- facturing progress. Methods Engineering. The extent to which work methods in detail are designed prior to production and then the (emphasis on improving these methods during production throug 1work simplification and similar programs will affect total rnanufacturing improvements. Production Planning and Control. This function may iFéicilitate progress through improved planning, routing, saczheduling, dispatching, and follow-up. This should result IiJrl an increased utilization of machines, tools, and labor , EiIan ultimately in a reduction in the direct labor hours nec- essary to manufacture a unit of production. Materials Management. When a materials management <-‘-<>‘151<2ept of organization is used this function may include the 15>]:"C>ciuction planning and control, the purchasing of raw mate- ITCi-éills and component parts, the control and the storage of 13“relaroduction, in-process and finished inventory and the .nu£3“t:<2rials handling function. If it is performed effectively, In. - . a":erial shortages and the disruption of production should 140 be reduced or eliminated. Product Engineering. This function is responsible for product design, specifications, testing, and the like. The extent to which manufacturability was considered prior to production and the degree of change required subsequently during production will influence total manufacturing improvg ment. Quality Control. The extent to which a quality assug ance program can reduce rework and repair operations, and scrap losses will affect the total manufacturing progress. The degree to which each and all of the above listed :Eactors may influence manufacturing progress will depend.upan tihe amount of available or possible improvement remaining ilumediately after the first unit of production has been.built IIt: seems reasonable to accept that a company that has spent In11ch.time and money getting the entire organization ready to start production of the first unit has a smaller potential fc>Ii‘manufacturing improvement after production has started tZIIEIn.a company that has started unprepared and plans to I'etrlove the inadequacies during manufacture. There is simply more room for progress for the second company than for the f.ij-tll‘sm. Let indices 1 and 2 designate the prepared and the unprepared company, respectively. Thus, in terms of the power 1311 . . 1r1<2tion model, their progress functions may be written as if Q:Llows: 141 -b1 -b2 Y1 — alx , and 72 = 32X a <lroduct and with this type of work will have a greater potep tIiQal for manufacturing progress. This is a possible ratio- Iléalle for the novelty hypothesis already mentioned in Chapter II- Preproduction Preparation, a Kind of Experience. The nChlelty hypothesis can be strengthened if preparation prior t:(:, Iproduction can be considered a kind of experience - - particularly if the fabrication of prototypes is part of the I) . j':“‘3:r)‘roductn.on effort. 143 The Assembly and Machining Progress Hypothesis. Some researchers have found that assembly operations exhibit significantly higher rates of progress than machining opera- tions (see Chapter II, pp 34 , and pp 50 ). The usual explanation is that in assembly work there is a relatively large scope for learning; in machine work the ability to reduce labor hours is greatly restricted by the fact that the machines cannot "learn" to run any faster.1 However, this hy- pothesis can be explained by the novelty hypothesis.Consider, for example Hirsch's study of the progress phenomenon in ma- chine-tool manufacturing. This study represents one of the few instances where the Assembly and Machining Progress hy— pothesis was explicitly tested. According to Hirsch, the possible reasons why the machining improvement rate is con- siderably less than the assembly improvement rate are: (l) Pfiany times the same part is used in both old and new models, (Jr even in different machines that, after many lots have been Ibiroduced, the actual improvement rate for each additional lot Ibeacomes almost negligible; (2) The accomplished machine oPerator can do little to improve his efficiency, since most C’15 his basic motions are the same, regardless of the part being produced, and (3) The third reason is due to the great jit1<2onsistency in the ratio of new to old parts used in the assembly of the different machines. Thus, machines comprised ()rf? a.large quantity of new parts will have a high rate of iTttrE>rovement, while machines with few new parts will have a l . O O O O 0 :)‘K7 improvement rate. Hirsch's explanation is con31stent w1th 144 the findings of Schultz and Conway. The Parameter Correlation Hypothesis. As mentioned hl Chapter II a strong correlation between the parameters of fire progress curve was found by H. Asher and N. Baloff. In Asher's study the correlation was found among startups that occurred in different facilities. In Baloff's study the cor- relation was among startups that occurred in the same facil— ity. However, the findings of both studies are consistent, i e., low values of parameter Q are associated with small p-parameter values, and high values of g with large, b_values. A tentative explanation is that management reacts to the reported level of initial productivity in ways that could tend to accelerate or decelerate the progress phenomenon. Startups that show a relatively "poor" beginning frequently liave more technical resources allocated to them, and are gen- errally "nurtured" to a greater extent, than startups that begin relatively well. Furthermore, judging from the comments (>1? many production personnel, it appears that the motivation 1F<>r progress within the production organization will be jtrrVersely correlated with the initial productivity. The moti ‘V’éitzion for productivity improvement is apparently stronger if?(>1? "poor" startups than for those that show a relatively large initial productivity. Both the "internal" motivation (szf the production organization and "external" management I:‘h‘tr'isfissure seem to be influenced in this way.4 145 MANUFACTURING PROGRESS - - A MODEL The conceptual framework presented in the previous section offers a basis for a model of the progress phenome- non in manufacturing industries. It seems desirable that such a model preserve the simplicity of wright's formulation while reflecting the generally accepted linearity hypothesis. Recall that this hypothesis states that linearity exists - - when in loga- rithmic coordinates - - between the labor per unit input and cumulative output. The model should also provide a means of predicting ‘the exact course of a startup, not just its functional form. ffhe usefulness of the model could be enhanced appreciably if some method of predicting the _a_ and 't_) parameters of the model for a given startup could be developed. The parameter (:cyrrelation hypothesis and the novelty hypothesis provide some basis to develop such a method. In explaining these hypotheses a common element emergai t311€3 potential for improvement. Implicit in the explanation €33i4\7en.in.the last section was the assumption that the poten- tial for improvement can be somehow estimated a priori and that management will strive to reach the estimated productiy i‘t2T57 'target. A model of the progress phenomenon should recog- I1 ‘ . 3L“==ej:‘iod. Therefore, for the first empirical observation, x1 W‘ :L‘:LC1 represent the number of units produced during the first F1" 147 month of production, and yl will be the average number of manhours per unit expended on these x1 units. Use of this lot convention, whose adoption is dictated by industrial accounting procedures, has several consequencmm the value of the g parameter is a theoretical one, except in the rare instance that only one airframe unit is produced during the first month of production. It can be argued that, even if the first accounting period yielded a cost for the first unit of an airframe, this cost figure would be suspect. It is a rare cost system that could accurately determine the cost of a single unit - - let alone the first unit - - of an airframe, given the nature of the production process and the industry. Moreover, it seems unlikely that first piece labor liours can be determined soon enough to enable their use as a pxredictor. To be useful for production decisions related to (Brigineering effort, production planning, manpower planning, <31? design changes, estimates far in advance of production ana necessary. Estimating the Ultimate Point (xu, yu) Given the difficulties in estimating the manhours con- S"J-l'l'led by the first unit produced, the progress function may gs't24i—ll be determined if some other point in future production 31-53 estimated. The so-called ultimate point (xu, yu) was 61 lready defined in Chapter II (p.39 ). Consider now some 148 aspects of its determination in practical work. Conventional estimating procedures, say the Methods- Time Measurement system (M.T.M.), are usually intended to give an estimate of the time that will be required after the 6 operation has "settled down". This estimate corresponds to the ordinate yu of the ultimate point. However, it is neces- sary to associate the conventional estimate yu with a specif ic point in cumulative production, x The most satisfactory u' way of doing this is to try not to disturb the existing estimating procedure but to examine its past performance to determine how long it took after production began for the actual time to decrease to the vicinity of the estimate. Presumably, (xu, yu) should be the point where the Inlateau begins. In practice it may not happen exactly this vvay. This fact does not impede the determination of the prog ress function. It suffices that the estimated labor hours per tJIlit at ultimate (yu) be reached at point xu in cumulative EDITOduction. Therefore (xu, yu) continues to be a point on the EDITOgress curve and can be used instead of the first point.In 13jilnns that have experience with production standards the E>Zliateau can be anticipated with reasonable accuracy. Once determination of point (x u’ yu) is made, the dif- Ifzi~<1ulties of obtaining first item labor hour are avoided. In 51':1 m MMDUHh onHmm>o 0.8 somm< 2888828 .58 9,2 $58 82 so 523.8 33580 o.m AIIIII somezoo monemm>o o.~ scmm< 32528808 8.48 a. momfi . mHmma n28 mmuzoz mm>c o.H onaomm onemHmUmmn azmwma z mazmzmmHacmm Hmoo w um>o onHmm>o ZMHmWw mmz 244 .53. 3252850 mm momq-emmmuHm mayo zmamwm mm: Mme mo o.H ammmmzsz a¢mumm>o .m mmmon 53sz AJ— mammmmom ZOHHUDQOMm Aest mmm mmaom momfiv 3.3 Hmoo Amm>o : OH mMDUHh o . 8 82883 SJ Aemommm 8 maHm mazmxampazHHADV mona 8 . .888 80888 28 880880 8 . 8.008 .88909..<8880 900 89820 80 880080 089088 -88 808 9800 8 .888 882 . 8.008 I.8<909.2089< 8880 980 9800 8 .882 882 . "Hmommm Hmoo d mmmom mm: HDQHDO 8.8 I 9000088\2089 88880 888 9800 028 88008 882 8088808 028 88909 8908200 8.8 208988880 80<8 I 808 880880 8 020 0 8898 -28888 8908200 H.m ZOHHMm>o I NH 55th MOHémnHo mmm <52 UZHMMOB .mo mHZMHUHMhMOU mmhflwm zmQMDm .w momj MHDQmmUm ZOHHUDQOME mHZHOnH MHSAHHHD MHHh hm: .anHZH CHAPTER VIII SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS The overall purpose of this study was to advance knowledge on the subject matter of Manufacturing Progress Functions. For the purpose of this dissertation the Manufac- turing Progress Function was generally defined as the re— lationship in which the labor input per unit used in the mag ufacture of a product tends to decline by a constant percenE age as the cumulative quantity produced is doubled. Where this relationship is present, it may be represented by a straight line in a double logarithmic scale. The prime objective of the study was to contribute a general symbolic-analytic model of the manufacturing progress phenomenon. Once the general model was established, an equally im- portant objective was to respond to the need for a coherent systematic approach to be used in predicting the develommaus of the adaptation process in industrial concerns of almost any kind. The foregoing general statement of purpose was broken down into a number of layers of investigation leading to the following more specific subobjectives: 248 249 l. A review of the literature that is of relevance to the objectives of the dissertation. 2. An investigation of the theory of the Manufacturing Progress Function aiming at a systematization of the existing body of knowledge, and at the derivation of new theoretical results that will settle the question of the parameters estimation of the general model. 3. The conception of a general symbolic-analytic model of the system adaptation phenomenon, including the develop ment of a method for using the model to predict the course of future startups. 4. The testing of the model in a number of real world sip uations by using data from diverse industrial operation; 5. The possibilities of implementing the model at firm level and national level. A brief recapitulation of the major points that have emerged from each chapter of the dissertation will serve to demonstrate thattfiuaaforementioned objectives were attained. Chapter 11 contains a comprehensive review of the his- torical development of the Manufacturing Progress Function and a summary of the more important contributions to the prq; ress curve literature that are relevant to this dissertation. Although the progress curve was discovered in 1922, it was largely unknown until World War II. T.P. Wright is given credit for originating the formulation of the progress curve theory in 1936. His statement, that cumulative average 250 manhours per unit decline by a constant percentage every time the output is doubled, remains the most popular formulation in existence. From 1940-1949, a number of modifications of the origi nal model were proposed. J.R. Crawford contributed the unit learning curve and noticed that different rates of progress might exist for different airframes. Several relevant contributions were published in the l950s.There was a pioneering effort by some researchers like W.Z. Hirsch, S.E. Bryan, R.W. Conway and A. Schultz, Jr. to extend the concept of the progress curve to labor-intensive industries other than the airframe industry.In addition,the studies by A. Alchian and H. Asher, in the airframe industry, together with Hirsch's study in the machine-tool industry, and Schultz and Conway's research in manufacturing of elec- tronic and electro-mechanical products represent objective and rigorous empirical investigations of the progress curve concept. The last fifteen years have seen some pioneering extep sions of the Manufacturing Progress Function to machine-inflql sive industries as well as to diverse labor-intensive indus- tries. The studies carried out by N. Baloff constitute the most comprehensive investigation of the progress function during this time. 251 It is worthwhile to review the main hypotheses raised bytfluaaforementioned authors: (i) Linearity, when in loga- rithmic coordinates, between the labor per unit input and cumulative output was generally confirmed except in Asher's study; (ii) There is no one single progress curve that can be universally applied to all types of operations involved h1 the manufacturing of a given product or to all products in a given firm or industry; (iii) Assembly operations experience higher rates of progress than machining operations; (iv) The findings are contradictory with respect to the novelty hy- potheses. Crawford, Schultz and Conway agree that the less similar a new product is to a predecessor, the greater the rate of progress experienced by the new product. Nevertheless, Alchian and Hirsch found in diverse settings that the greater the similarity of a product to a predecessor, the greater dug rate of progress experienced by the new product; (v) Baloff found a strong correlation between the parameters of the startup model among startups that occurred in the same produg tion facility whereas Asher noticed a strong correlation among startups that occurred in different facilities; (vi) Plateaux predictability continues to be a controversial issue. The field of progress functions lacks notation uniform; ty, precise definition of the variables and functional rela- tionships involved, and formal mathematical proofs of several assumed results. A coherent mathematical exposition can be the basis for the derivation of new important results. Such theoretical systematization is offered in Chapter III 252 Initially, four types of progress functions are identified. Functional relationships for the four types are clearly and compactly defined with recourse to set theory notation.Param eters g and p are explained and interpreted. In a second sep tion, four fundamental problems which users might have faced consciously or unconsciously, are formally stated and solved, at times by more than one method. Finally, parameter calculg tion problems are classified and solved by exact or approxi- mate formulas. Chapter IV represents a continuation of the mathematical exposition initiated in Chapter III. Two related topics of practical relevance are approached: the integration of prog- ress functions and the debatable problem of their aggregathL Original approximations are proposed for both problems. A general symbolic—analytic model of the manufacturing progress phenomenon is offered in Chapter V. Some effort is also expended in questioning the causes of the systematic gains in productivity embodied in the progress curve. Thus, a tentative concept of manufacturing progress is proposed where the number of available hypotheses is reduced to a minimum and the explanatory power of the remaining hypoth- eses is greatly enhanced. It is suggested that the manufacturing progress phenom enon can be described and its course predicted by the follow ing empirical equations: 253 y = ax'b (8.1) and b = m + n 1n a, (8.2) where y = y/yu a= a/yu and (xu, yu) is the estimated ultimate point. In Chapter VI the manufacturing progress model pre- sented in Chapter V is tested with real data from nine manp facturers representing five different industries. A hundred and fifty-nine separate cases of product and process startups that occurred in four different countries and nine distinct plants have been analyzed. In addition, aggregate data was obtained for whole industries in one country, yielding nine more startups. The major conclusions that have emerged from the empip ical research are the following: (1) The descriptive efficiency of the manufacturing progress model given by equation (8.1) is generally supported by the results of regression analysis of the startups from firms A,B,C,D,E,F,G,H,I, and industry J. The coefficients of determination r2 (2) (3) 254 vary from 0.59 to 1.000, with a median value of 0.969. In only ten per cent of the cases does the regression fail to explain at least 81.7% of the total variance in the dependent variable. The t-ratios are generally impressive, ranging from 2.08 to 99.99, with a median value of 10.9. If normality and common variance are assumed, the null hypotheses p = 0 and B = 0 can be rejected at the 0.95 level of significance in 95% of the startups analyzed. The descriptive efficiency of the parameter model given by equation (8.2) is generally supported by the results of regression analysis of the startup parameters from firms A,D,E,F,G,H,I and industry J. The parameter model is supported among opera- tions of the same product (firms A and G), among products within the same plant (firms D,E,F,H and I), and among groups of products of similar technology within the same industrial sector of a foreign economy (industry J). The findings of this research and previous findings by Asher and Baloff constitute adequate evidence to suggest that the parameter model can be devel- oped into an effective means of predicting the parameter p of a new startup. However, additional investigation and validation is necessary for 255 successful industrial application of the model. The dissertation is concluded (Chapter VII) with a discussion of the industrial implications of the findings reported in Chapter VI. The importance of recognizing and predicting the manufacturing progress phenomenon is related to several decision—making functions that are encountered in an industrial setting as well as in economic planning at the national level. Finally, an overall design of a computerized Manufacturing Progress Function (MPF) System is suggested. APPENDICES APPENDIX A 256 APPENDIX A MATHEMATICAL PROOFS (1) A FORMAL PROOF THAT lim 8:43 = + co x+0 The above statement means that for each positive number M it is possible to find a positive number 6 (depending on M in general) such that —a—b->M when 0<|x|<6 x To prove this, note that i%-> M when 0< N To prove this, note that for -b lax |‘(§. /b e l/b Choosing N = (2) , the required result follows. APPENDIX B APPENDIX B EQUATION OF THE ASYMPTOTE TO THE CURVE REPRESENTING THE LOGARITHM OF THE UNIT PROGRESS FUNCTION The following theorem of Mathematical Analysis is used: ”If an infinite branch of a curve has an asymptote y = cx + d, the coefficients p_and Q will be given by NM c = lim and d = lim (y - cx) (B.l) X+°° x+oo where the point M(x,y) remains on the branch of the curve. And, conversely, if the limits in (3.1) exist when M(x,y) moves to infinity along a branch of the curve, the straight line y = cx + d will be an asymptote of that branch. ” Let F [log(x):] = log { alEcl-b - (x-l)1-b:]} (B.2) One must show that f(log x) = log [a(l-bi] - b log x is asymptote to F [log (xij given by (B.2) Coefficient p pf the Asymptote According to the forementioned theorem: 258 lim x+oo lim 259 log aLxl-b - (x-1)-§] (108 X)+m 108 x lim x—>oo E l-b l-b] log a + log x - (x-l) log x Applying L'Hospital's rule, it follows that: log lim x—mo lim x+oo x+oo log x 1 1 '7 -b b ' (l-b)l_x -(x-1) .] 1 .. 1n-0 [x1 b _ (x_1)1 b] 1. . I lnlO x (l-b) x [-bx b'l - igl- x'b‘z - ] (l-b) b + (l-b)b -b-1 + 2! «bx.b _ -b -b X Coefficient d of the Asymptote According to the previously stated theorem and using the result c = -b, it follows that: d = lim (log x)+w {log a [8 260 1"” - (x-1)1”b] + b 10g x} = lim log {a [xl-b - (x-l)1-§] xb} x+oo = log a + lim x+oo x+oo = log a + lim x+oo = log a + log Equation of the Since c - -b log {xb [x1 b - (x-l)l :1} log {xb [(I-b)x‘b + “—51% bx‘b'l + ..J} 1.. [(1-8 +0538. 515+ ...] 118L145) +$lflb 1+ H] x+w 2! x (l-b) = log [a(l-bZ] Asymptote to F [log(x)j - b and d = log [8 (l-bX] , the equation of the asymptote f(log x) to F [log (x):] = log {a [xl'b - (x-l)1-b:]} 261 is, according to the forementioned theorem: f(log x) = - b log x + log Ea(l-b):] (q.e.d.) APPENDIX C APPENDIX C PARAMETER FORMULAS DERIVATION In chapter V it was suggested that the manufacturing progress phenomenon can be described and its course predicted by the following equations y = ax-b (Cl) and b=m+nln a (C2) where y = XLEL yu _ EL a - yu and (xu,yu) is the estimated ultimate point. If the best fit to the available data is achieved with the cumulative-average progress function, the productivity index y will have to be defined as In this case, prediction of parameters g and p for a new startup can be developed as follows. 262 263 Equation (Cl) yields for x = xu : F( ) - x“ = ax b (C3) yu u If the best fit is given by the cumulative-average prog b ress function §'= ax' , then: § % a<1-b> x‘b (CS) u u Dividing (C4) by (C5), yields: $122; = 1%5 (C6) ' u Substituting in (C3) the result obtained in (C6) and solving for a, yields: __Lb a.- l-b xu (C7) Substituting in (C2) the result obtained in (C7) it follows that: b = m + n 1n (I%B-x:) or 264 b n ln ({¥%) - b + m.= 0 (C8) Equation (C8) can be solved for pyby the Newton-Raphsan Method as follows: n [b 1n xu - 1n (l-b)j - b + m = O f(bl) = nEbl ln xu - ln (l-blZJ- b1 + m = 0 I _. ___—1 - = f (b1) n (1n xu + 1'b1) 1 O nEa lnx -ln(1-b):'-b +m b2 = bl _ 1 u 1 1 (c9) 1 n [1n xu + I:b:] - l After some iterations of formula ( 9) it is possible to obtain an adequate approximation b* of b. By substituting b* in (07), it follows that: _ 1 b* a,— l-b xu and b* a = yut, = 1_b (c10) APPENDIX D APPENDIX D STABILITY OF COEFFICIENTS 9 AND E OF THE PARAMETER.MODEL The following is a check on the stability of coeffi- cients m and n of the parameter model: b = m + n ln 3 In the case of firm D (14 products), sample 1 was tdflfll randomly from products D1 through D14. Sample 2 is formed by the remaining products. Data tables are in page 268. In the case of firm F (28 products), sample 1 was taken randomly from products Fl through F28. Sample 2 is formed by the re- maining products. Data tables are in pages 278-79 The following calculations were then carried out: (1) Estimation of the regression of b on ln a for samples 1 and 2 of each firm; (2) Variances about regressions l and 2; (3) Difference between the two regression coefficients n1 and n2: variance, standard error and confidence limits; (4) Dif- ference between the two intercepts m1 and m2: variance, stap dard error and confidence limits; (5) Test of the hypothesis that the variances about the two regressions are equal. It is concluded that the difference between the two .regression coefficients is not statistically significant.The same goes for the difference between the two intercepts. 265 266 In the final section of Appendix D a comparison is made between two approaches for predicting parameter b and §;values of new startups, namely, by using average b and g values taken from past data and by employing the parameter model approach proposed in Chapter V. Sample 1 (Table D.5) was drawn randanLy from firm F binding machines and simulataspast data. Sample 2 (Table D.6) is formed by the remaining types of binding ma- chines produced by firm F. Predictions were then carried out for parameters b and g of the products in Sample 2 by using data available from Sample 1. The results of the comparison are exhibited in Tables D.7 and D.8. The actual values of b and 3 appear in column (2) of each table, respectively. The average b's and 3's - - calculated from Sample 1 values - — are in column (3). Per cent deviations of the predictionsrmde by using average values with respect to the actual values are in column (4). The predictions for b and §_made by using the parameter model are in column (5). Detailed calculations pre- cede Tables D.7 and D.8. Per cent deviations of the parameter model predictions b and g ‘with respect to the actual values P P of b and g are in column (6) of each table. The mean absolute deviation is defined as = 2 [Prediction Errors] M.A.D. No. of Predictions From the results in Tables D.7 and D.8, the following M.A.D. values were calculated through the above formula: 267 (1) Predictions using averages of past data 0.0815 1.24 b parameter : M.A.D. a parameter : M.A.D. (2) Predictions using the parameter model b parameter : M.A.D. 0.0497 g parameter : M.A.D. 0.502 Similar results were obtained with the data pertaining to printing presses produced by firm F and with the data available from other firms (e.g., firms G and I). The author believes that the parameter model contributed in Chapter V has proved to be superior to other existing methods for estimathu; the parameters of new startups. FIRM D (14 products) TABLE D.1 SAMPLE l, FIRM D PRODUCTS 3 1n a b D3 1.341 0.2934 0.0936 D11 3.521 1.259 0.220 D4 2.483 0.9095 0.275 D14 1.333 0.2874 0.0533 D5 1.230 0.2070 0.0543 D7 5.252 1.658 0.333 D12 7.002 1.946 0.406 TABLE D.2 SAMPLE 2, FIRM D PRODUCTS 3 1n 3' b D10 6.945 1.938 0.409 Dl 2.649 0.9742 0.368 D2 3.230 1.173 0.297 D6 2.882 1.059 0.205 D9 1.625 0.4855 0.0929 D8 1.156 0.1450 0.0226 D13 6.683 1.900 0.409 269 l- ESTIMATION OF THE REGRESSION OF b ON In E (LET b = y and 1n 3 = x) REGRESSION 1 (sample 1) n = no. of observations = 7 2x = 6.5603; i = 5% = 0.9372 n 2(x - §)2 = x2 - (2x)2/n' = 9.1597 - 6.56032/7 = 3.0115 2y = 1.4352; y = §X = 0.2050 n’ — 2 2 2 . 2 Z(y - y) = 2y - (1y) /n = 0.4143 - 1.4352 /7 = 0.1200 2(x—§)(y-§) = zxy - zxzy/n' = 1.9233 - 6-56°3’7‘1°‘*352==0.5783 The regression coefficient n is given by l = Z(x - §)(y -4§) = 0.5783 _ 0.1920 :3 H I 2 2(x - R) 3.0115 The regression equation of y on x is then: I-< II §’+ n1 (x — i) = 0.2050 + 0.1920 (x - 0.9372) or Y 0.0251 + 0.1920 x 270 or B = 0.0251 + 0.1920 1n 3 where: ml= 0.0251(intercept) and n1 = 0.1920 (slope) REGRESSION 2 (sample 2) 2x 7.6747; R =sz/n" = 1.0964 _ 2 2 2(x - X) = 11.0691 - 7.6747 /7 = 2.6547 Zy = 1.8035; y = Ey/n" = 0.2567 £(y - §)2 = 0.6094 - 1.80352/7 = 0.1447 (x - §)(y - y) = 2.5421 - 7 6747 g 1-3035 8 0.5648 n2 = %f%%%% = 0.2128 (regression coefficient) The regression equation of y on x is then: Y = y + n2(x - §) = 0.2576 + 0.2128 (x - 1.0964) or Y 0.0244 + 0.2128 x 'or B 0 0244 + 0.2128 1n 3 271 where: 012 = 0.0244(intercept) and n2 = 0.2128 (slope) 2 - VARIANCE ABOUT THE REGRESSION VARIANCE ABOUT REGRESSION l The sum of squares about the regression is given by 2(y-Y)2=z(y-§)2-z/<1 + «12) The variance of the regression coefficient is given by: 2 O V (n) = (D.2) 2 2(x - 35) Substituting S for O in (D.2) yields: _ 2 V (n1) = 32/ 21(x — x) and V (n ) 2 _—2 2 S/22(x x) where 21(x - i)2 is based on the observations from which 111 was calculated and similarly for 22(x - §)2. Therefore, since I11 and 112 are independent estimates: v (nl-n ) = $2 1 + 1 (D.3) 2 21 (x3102 22 (x-i’)2 _ 1 1 and S.E.(bl-bz) - s _ 2 + _ 2 (DA) 21(x-x) 22(x-x) 274 These enable confidence limits for the difference to be calculated, using the value of t with (01 + 02) degrees of freedom. If the variances about the two regressions cannot be assumed equal, then the confidence limits must be calculated by another method. We assume that the variances are equal (this assumption will be tested in a later section). Thus, 02 is estimated by $2 = 0.5 (0.00178 + 0.00490) = 0.00334 The variance and the standard error of the difference between I11 and 112 are calculated as follows: 2 1 l 1 1 - =S + =0.0034 -————-+———— V(n1 n2) [21(x-x)2 22(x-x)2:l 3 [3.0115 2.6547] = 0.002367 % S.E. (n1 - n2) = (0.002367) = 0.0487 Confidence Limits Using t with (01 + ¢2) = 10 degrees of freedom, the 95% confidence limits are: .l. (nl - n2) - 2.23 S.E. (nl-nz) = (0.1920-0.2128) f2.23x0.0487 - 0.1294 to 0.0878 275 Since the confidence limits include zero, the difference between the regression coefficients 111 and n2 is not statisti cally significant. 4 - THE DIFFERENCE BETWEEN THE TWO INTERCEPTS m1 AND m2 The variance of the intercept m is given by: 2 i2 V(m) = O (D-5) 504 + 2(x-i) Substituting S for O in (D.5) yields _2 x V(ml) = 82 8L.+ 1 I 2 n 2 (x-x) l 2 1 £2 V(m2) = S _— + ___—2- n" 2 (x-i) 2 Since 1111 and m2 are independent estimates and n' = n" 8.11-1.2) = 32 .2. + ___.1— + 2 n 21(x-§)2 22(x-i)2 2 2 0.00334 (.3. + MALL + _1_-_0_9_6_‘L_) 3.0115 2.6547 0.003441 276 } S.E. (m1 - 82) = (0.003441)2 = 0.0587 Confidence Limits Using t with (01 + 02) = 10 degrees of freedom, the 95% limits are (ml - m2) T 2.23 x S.E.(ml-mz) = (0.0251-0.0244) f 2.23x0.0587 =-0.1302 to 0.1316 Since the confidence limits include zero, the difference between the intercepts m1 and 102 is not statistically significant. Note. If the variances about the two regressions cannot be assumed equal, then the confidence limits must be calculated by another method. In the following section the hypothesis 2 2 2 2 Hozol = 02 is tested w1th H¢ : 01 ¢ 02 . 5 — TEST OF THE HYPOTHESIS THAT THE VARIANCES ABOUT THE TWO REGRESSIONS ARE EQUAL. When the populations are normally distributed and the samples are independent, the ratio of two samples variances is distributed according to the F distribution and has the test statistic 2 Sllo l-‘N F: S 2 lo2 2 2 277 2 2 where S and 8: are the sample variances and o and Oi are the population variances from which the samples were takem The hypothesis is that 0% = 0%, and the estimates of these an) parameters are represented by their unbiased estimates Si and 8%. Consequently, the test statistics reduces to _ 2 2 Since Si = 0.00490 and 8% = 0 00178, F = 0.00490/0.00178 = 2.76 We have also: 01 = 02 = 5 degrees of freedom From the table of the variance ratio (F - Distribution), the 5% and 1% points are 5.05 and 11.0, respectively. 02 = O: is accepted. Thus, the hypothesis HO : 1 FIRM F (28 products) TABLE D . 3 SAMPLE 1, FIRM F PRODUCTS 3 1n 3 b F24 4.74 1.556 0.228 F18 2.70 0.9933 0.176 F11 1.48 0.3920 0.0758 F12 1.80 0.5878 0.148 F21 2.02 0.7031 0.123 F17 3.42 1.230 0.237 F7 1.77 0.5710 0.123 F20 4.47 1.497 0.235 F28 3.16 1.151 0.227 F19 2.71 0.9969 0.186 F13 3.85 1.348 0.271 F26 1.57 0.4511 0.0731 F25 2.41 0.8796 0.120 Fl 3.57 1.273 0.238 279 TABLE D.4 SAMPLE 2, FIRM F -,— ___ PRODUCTS a_ 1n a b F5 2.01 0.6981 0.147 F6 1.99 0.6881 0.150 F4 1.97 0.6780 0.184 F27 1.95 0.6678 0.131 F9 1.93 0.6575 0.136 F3 1.83 0.6043 0.110 F10 1.80 0.5878 0.128 F2 1.49 0.3988 0.0604 F8 1.36 0.3075 0.0551 F16 4.94 1.597 0.246 F15 3.22 1.169 0.219 F22 3.17 1.154 0.201 F23 2.80 1.030 0.133 F14 2.59 0.9517 0.172 280 1 - ESTIMATION OF THE REGRESSION OF b ON In g 011' or (LET b = y AND 1n 3 = x) REGRESSION 1 no. of observations = 14 :3 II Xx 13.6298; i = Zx/n' = 0.9736 2(x-§)2 = 2x2 - (Zx)2/n' 2y = 2.4609; § = Zy/n' = 0.1758 2(y-7)2 = Eyz - (Zy)2/n' 15.2147-13.62982/14 = 1.9453 O.4882-2.46092/14= 0.05563 13.6298 x 2.4609 Z(x-§)(y-y) = 2xy - Zny/n' = 2.6998 - = 0.3040 The regression coefficient n1 is given by n1 = Z(x-x)(yey) = 0.3040 = 0 1563 )3 (x-§) 2 1. 9453 The regression equation of y on x is then: 14 Y = y + nl (x - E) = 0.1758 + 0.1563 (x - 0.9736) F< ll 0.0236 + 0.1563 x 00 ll 0 0236 + 0.1563 In 3 231 where: m = 0.0236 (intercept) and n = 0.1563 (slope) or or 1 1 REGRESSION 2 n" = 14 11.1896; R = Ex/n" = 0.7993 Xx 2(x-32)2 = 10.4784 - 11.18962/14 = 1.5350 2y = 2.0725; § = Zy/n” = 0.1480 2(y-§)2 = 0.3449 - 2.07252/14 = 0.03810 11.1896 x 2.0725 2(x-§)(y-§) = 1.8717 - = 0.2152 14 n2 = 2.2—1.5.; = 01402 1.5350 The regression equation of y on x is then: Y = y:+ n2 (x-i) = 0.1480 + 0.1402 (x - 0.7993) Y = 0.0359 + 0.1402 x B = 0.0359 + 0.1402 1n a where m = 0.0359 (intercept) and n = 0.1402 (slope) 2 2 282 2 - VARIANCE ABOUT THE REGRESSION VARIANCE ABOUT REGRESSION 1 The sum of squares about the regression is given by 2(y-Y)2 = z2 - 208302 (D.6) Sum of squares of observations y about their mean Z(y - §)2 = 0.05563 Sum of squares due to the regression 2 (Sr-37) 2 _ _ _ 2 _ b2 >22 = [2(x-x)(y-y) ] /2:2 0.30402/1.9453 0.04751 Substituting in (D.6) yields: 2 2(y—Y) = 0.05563 - 0.04751 = 0.00812 Hence, the variance about the regression is estimatedtnr 52 _ 0.00812 1 - 12 = 0.000677 (Since the sum of squares about the regression is based on n' — 2 = 14 - 2 = 12 degrees of freedom.) 283 VARIANCE ABOUT REGRESSION 2 Similarly, we have: 2(y - §)2 = 0 03810 _ 2 2 2(Y - y) = 0.2152 /1 5350 = 0.03017 2(y - Y)2 = 0.03810 - 0.03017 = 0.00793 Hence, the variance about the regression is estimatedtun 3% = 0.00793/12 = 0.000661 3 - THE DIFFERENCE BETWEEN THE TWO REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS 2 . . . . . O , the error variance Is estimated by combining Si and Si as follows: (D II 0.5 (0.000677 + 0.000661) 0.000669 The variance and the standard error of the difference between nl and 112 are calculated as follows 2 1 1 1 1 = . + 21(x-i)21-22(x-§)2 0 000669 1.9453 1.5350 I U) V(n1-n2) — 0.001463 284 S.E. (n1 - n2) = (0.001463)% = 0.0382 Confidence Limits Using t with (¢1 + ¢2) = 24 degrees of freedom, the 95% confidence limits are (nl-nz) T 2.06 S.E.(n (0.1563-0.1402)T 2.06 x 0.0382 1‘n2) -0.0626 to 0.0948 Since the confidence limits include zero, the diffemence between the regression coefficients n1 and n2 is not statisti cally significant. 4 - THE DIFFERENCE BETWEEN THE TWO INTERCEPTS m AND m . l 2 The variance and the standard error of the difference (m1 - m2) are calculated as follows: x x V(ml-m2) = 82 _;,+ ————l——— + 2 n 21(x-§)2 22(x-§) 2 2 g; + 0.9736 + 0.7993 14 1.9453 1.5350 = 0.000669 = 0.0007000 }« S.E.(ml - m2) = (0.0007000)2 = 0.0265 285 Confidence Limits Using t with (01 + ¢2) = 24 degrees of freedom, the 95% limits are (ml-m2) f 2.06 S.E.(ml—m2)=(0.0236-0.0359) t 2.06 x 0.0265 = -0.0669 to 0.0423 Since the confidence limits include zero, the difference between the intercepts m1 and m2 is not statistically significant. 5 - TEST OF THE HYPOTHESIS H :02 = 02 0 1 2 . 2 2 Since S1 = 0.000677 and 82 = 0.000661, _ 0.000677 = F ’ 0.000661 1'02 We have also: 01 = 02 = 12 degrees of freedom. From the table of the variance ratio (F-Distribution), the 5% and 1% points are 2.69 and 4.16, respectivelly. Thus, the hypothesis H oi = o: is accepted. 02 286 PREDICTING PARAMETER b AND a VALUES OF NEW STARTUPS (FIRM F, BINDING MACHINES) TABLE D.5 SAMPLE l (SIMULATES PAST DATA) PRODUCT a In a b F15 3.22 1.169 0.219 F12 1.80 0.5878 0.148 F14 2.59 0.9517 0.172 F9 1.93 0.6575 0.136 Fl 3.57 1.273 0.238 F6 1.99 0.6881 0.150 TABLE D.6 SAMPLE 2 (SIMULATES NEW STARTUPS) PRODUCT a 1n a b F7 1.77 0.5710 0.123 F8 1.36 0.3075 0.0551 F10 1.80 0.5878 0.128 Fll 1.48 0.3920 0.0758 F13 3.85 1.348 0.271 F16 4.94 1.597 0.246 287 REGRESSION EQUATION (FROM SAMPLE 1) b = 0.0518 + 0.141 1n 3 "ULTIMATES" PRODUCT xu yu F7 37 236 F8 32 241 F10 33 168 F11 39 215 F13 88 295 F16 110 169 PREDICTIONS Product F7 Parameter b Parameter b is calculated through equation (C.9), as follows: _ n [b1 1n xu - 1n (l-b1)_l - bl + m b2 = bl Set b1 = 0.100 288 b = 0 100 _ 0 141 [0.100 ln 37-1n(1-0.100):l- 0.100+0.0518 2 . 1 0.141 (1n 37'*1-o.100) - 1 0.0176 _ -o.334 ‘ 0'153 0.100 - Set b2 = 0.153 b _ o 153 _ 0.141 [0.153 In 37-ln (1—o.153):J- 0.153+0.0518 3 1 0.141(11‘1 37 + m) - 1 0.000112 -0.324 Ilz 0.153 - 0.153. Parameter a Parameter a is calculated through equation (C.10) as follows: b a = 1&1 _ 370.153 _ 2 05 - l-b l-0.153 ' Product F8 Parameter b Set 61 = 0.100 0.141 [0.100 In 32 - ln (140.100):]-»0.100+0.0518_ 1 0 141 (1n 32 1-0.100) 0.100 - b2 0.364 S€t b2 = 0.364 289 0 141 [0.364 1n 32-1n(1-0.364:fl - 0 364+0.0518 0.141 (In 32 + Set b = 0.121 1 1-0.364) - 1 _ 0 121 0 141 [0.121 In 32-—1n(1-0.121):]- O.121+0.0518 0.141 (In 32 + ITELIET) - 1 = 0.144 Set b4 = 0.144 b5 a 0.144 Product F10 Similarly we have: Parameter b b = 0.146 Parameter a b xu 330.146 e=1t6=mz6=1-95 290 Product Fll Parameter b b = 0.157 Parameter a Product F13 Parameter b b = 0.251 Parameter a Product F16 Parameter b b = 0.306 Parameter a a = iii = llQELEES = 6 07 _ l-b 1-0.306 ° 291 RESULTS TABLE D.7 PREDICTED PARAMETER b VALUES (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) PRODUCT b B A% bp A% (actual) F7 0 123 0.177 44 0.153 24 F8 0.0551 0 177 221 0.144 161 F10 0.128 0.177 38 0.146 14 Fll 0.0758 0.177 134 0.157 107 F13 0.271 0.177 -35 0.251 -7.4 F16 0 246 0.177 -28 0.306 24 TABLE D.8 PREDICTED PARAMETER a VALUES (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) PRODUCT i} E A% 3p A% (actual) F7 1.77 2.52 42 2.05 16 F8 1 36 2.52 85 1.92 41 F10 1 80 2.52 40 1.95 8.3 F11 1.48 2.52 70 2.11 42 F13 3.85 2.52 -35 4.11 6.7 F16 4.94 2.52 -49 6.07 23 APPENDIX E APPENDIX E xu A CODE FOR CALCULATING ail WITH AN 1 HP-25 SCIENTIFIC PROGRAMMABLE POCKET CALCULATOR Switch to PRGM mode and press f PRGM to clear program memory and display step 00. Then key in the list of keys below: Kevs Comments b Enter parameter b_value a Enter parameter a value x Enter xu value 293 To run the program switch to automatic RUN mode and press f PRGM so that the calculator will begin execution from step 00. Press R/S to start execution. When execution stops press RCL 2 to retrieve the result stored in register R2 10 It takes approximately 20 seconds to compute a 22 x-b l APPENDIX F DATA TABLES (CHAPTER VI) 294 TABLE 6.3 FINAL ASSEMBLY OF THE CPU OF A THIRD GENERATION COMPUTER (FIRM A) Startup Productivity Index (y) at Cum. Unit Code 1 2 3 4 5 A1 1.87 1.68 1.65 1.49 1.39 A2 1.68 1.59 1.49 1.38 1.30 A3 2.70 2.18 1.94 1.76 1.63 A4 2.40 2.26 1.95 1.80 1.67 A5 2.12 1.92 1.72 1.58 1.47 TABLE 6.4 MANUFACTURING OF CARD PUNCH X (FIRM A) Startup Productivity Index (y) at Cumulative Unit Code 94 183 277 421 584 757 A6 1.53 1.39 1.34 1.29 1.21 1.16 A7 1.22 1.05 1.00 1.00 1.00 1.00 A8 1.24 1.13 1.09 1.15 1.11 1.08 A9 1.71 1.65 1.63 1.53 1.38 1.29 A10 1.89 1.68 1.60 1.42 1.31 1.24 A11 1.81 1.67 1.61 1.47 1.34 1.26 295 TABLE 6.5 ASSEMBLY OF MAJOR UNITS OF CARD PUNCH Y (FIRM A) Startup Productivity Index (y) at Cumulative Unit Code 111 155 214 287 394 575 A12 1.34 1.31 1.29 1.27 1.21 1.16 TABLE 6.6 FINAL ASSEMBLY & TESTING OF CARD PUNCH X (FIRM B) Startup Productivity Index (y) at Cumulative Unit Code 15 40 52 358 1007 1912 B1 2.44 2.52 2.37 1.61 1.38 1.22 TABLE 6.7 FINAL ASSEMBLY OF CARD PUNCH Y (FIRM C) Startup Productivity Index (y) at Cumulative Unit Code 40 84 134 195 264 340 410 490 580 680 800 Cl 3.07 2.73 2.52 2.33 2.18 2.06 1.99 1.91 1.84 1.76 1.70 920 1050 1180 1320 1470 1610 1780 1940 2140 1.64 1.59 1.54 1.50 1.46 1.43 1.39 1.37 1.33 296 TABLE 6.8 ASSEMBLY OF 2nd GENERATION COMPUTER UNITS (FIRM D, PROGRAM # 1) Startup Productivity Index (y) at Cumulative Unit Code 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 D1 2.68 2.02 1.75 1.60 1.48 D2 3.12 2.59 2.38 2.26 2.06 1.92 1.81 1.73 1.66 1.59 1.54 D3 1.31 1.28 1.23 1.19 1.16 1.13 1.11 1.09 1.09 1.08 D4 2.47 2.05 1.89 1.66 D5 1.23 1.16 1.19 1.16 1.12 1.10 D6 2.86 2.57 2.23 2.23 2.05 1.99 1.89 1.83 1.84 1.82 1.79 (cont'd) 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 D6 1. 74 1.69 1.69 1.68 1.66 1.64 1.60 1.58 1.54 1.52 1.49 297 TABLE 6.9 ASSEMBLY OF SMALL COMPUTER COMPONENTS (FIRM D, PROGRAM # 2) Startup Productivity Index (y) at Cumulative Unit Code 5 10 15 20 23 30 37 38 39 40 D7 3.07 2.44 1.95 1.70 '1.57 D8 1.13 1.07 1.09 1.08 1.06 D9 1.38 1.33 1.25 1.18 1.14 D10 3.51 2.82 2.05 1.70 D11 2.41. 2.12 2.03 1.53 D12 3.56 2.83 2H39 1.90 D13 3.37 2.73 1.96 1.64 D14 1.23 1.16 1Jl6 1H14 1.12 1.09 298 TABLE 6.10 ASSEMBLY OF COMPUTER COMPONENTS AND DATA STORAGE UNITS (FIRM E) Startup Productivity Index (y) at Cumulative Unit Code 5 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 E1 4.35 4.58 2.86 2.31 2.03 1.94 1.82 1.73 1.65 E2 1.89 1.80 1.71 1.55 1.47 1.31 E3 2.59 2.32 2.25 2.09 1.92 1.80 1.70 1.59 E4 2.73 2.28 2.06 1.91 1.73 1.61 1.51 1.43 E5 2.89 2.57 2.32 2.33 2.15 2.00 1.86 1.74 2.43 2.30 2.18 2.07 E6 3.34 3.24 2.96 2.85 2.70 2.59 2.55 2.50 E7 2.94 2.19 1.79 1.77 1.60 1.49 E8 2.03 2.00 1.56 1.48 1.35 1.29 E9 5.14 4.08 3.47 2.87 2.53 2.31 2.10 1.94 E10 2.23 2.14 1.75 1.72 1.59 1.53 1.44 E11 3.79 4.03 3.28 3.07 2.76 2.59 2.52 2.38 2.21 E12 2.98 2.53 2.04 1.99 1.85 1.65 1.56 mom we: woc.aal una.m3 cos-man ovoeml hh=.Nl 80...». c:«.n:o mno.nu «3oowan csmo:uu :on.¢~0 www.mnt wwueoml www.0I omwocl Nmneol :ma.wul ous-:0 mmm.~0 ~m~.no «vs-out "whoou 033.00 nma.aoo ow~.an whdocu mloqaoh coo. ~Nc. Now. moo. omm. ace.“ moo. mws. :ow. mew. mew. how. :wm. mmm. ”mo. omw. mom. cmc. awm. own. cow. Goo. nn0. mam. mww. sww. noo.n scoot mm@.o acoot nosot ooa.« mmmol “mo.o mmweu memo- Mwoou mom.l smmeu ~5m.n ouwou chaol ~m060 -0.0 sc~.l Nmoei nomol mom.o mom.n one.« :m@.0 noo.o «a mmmmmoooooomoem.~=:o~mmmc::r .mmo no ~¢mn. Some. rnmxo msnao msom. «:05. :hoc. «mom. some. ~hmo. swam. amNN. ammo. 5:00. ouao. owoc. hum». mwdwo nmow. ~«30. mmdo. ammo. ammo. coon. now”. some. macaw brand: «woo doa3.n Nom~.o megs-I mwoa.l o-a.t mwmn.o mmo~.3 m:mo.t o:-.u pmoo.l :~m~.0 muon.t cc«~.I o:o«.n mooe.l onsw.l h:o~.| -nd.l momaol mnea.l nsma.l QNNN.0 ounweo «dan.n Nsmqel :m~«.o - < «meuuaeee ymcuzqyee messmmm zoemmmeeme eoeeozat mmueunye mama» moc.~ amm.n mPo.o mmo.« mmaou mm~.m ~mo.~ omm.a nn4.~ d3n.« nMN.» m:c.~ an~.h ~o«.: mmo.~ «ou.: mne.¢ nm~.m mam.“ dus.“ nNh.~ nsH.~ ma:.~ ho~.~ Nwhaa mow.“ was «ac age we no No we do ‘1 1' we «o «o «m Nun add cad C4 w o< ad 44 ma ,9 c nd moo.o:l moo. mwmoc m :Noo. Nn:«.s mao.d man snh.:oa woo. coo-«I m wQJm. mmna.u shr.a and nanomu 00¢. «00.0 m Pmum. ms~w.t was.” can omm.~«3 «cm. 500.0 m @090. Nona-n Nmo.a cm o@@.eo «ma. mm069 c mwmo. ammc.l 5mm.” cu now.::l cwm. woo.» m Noam. Nn~«.| ask.“ an «ow-n30 cmo. mmmeu m nuow. com«.| «mw.« on :no.««1 Jam. Noo.l n anew. ~h:«.n :«o.~ m womool who. 500.! m moon. mno«.n “hm.“ 4m s¢c.:o @oc. m:mol m momm- mmoa.l mmm.« Mu maceno hmh. chaol m comm. :ooooo cm:.« N Noa.w~o now. 000.: o Noam. osm~.1 women «m hcdowml mow. :maol s mo3c. m~n~.| o:n.: Nam «neon- new. «moon m 9:00. maH~.I m30.m «am beheado mom. memo- s «new. :0~«.| mko.n mum ohuoowt com. M006: a :ons. «mon.t Nao.w mm uan.o| mcm. mhmen a «wow. c:«~.l saaon cm mon.o«| Jaw. ~coeo o smug. nos~.n mmn.¢ mm nmneadu mam. omo.l wu whom. no:«ou ~¢:.: Em schocl owo. noool Q emcee o:~«.o «do.» mu own-owl who. amoos c mocc. acnwoa :no.: 4m cdaocl Nwo. covet a some. onmd.n mam.n mm owm.wl :«m. omooc 0 «com. N~:«.I a~:.N mm nnmcouc mam. ~sooo .o #553. noun.l oneoo am 463.». 53w. num.u o .~nmw. nnmo.| nnn.« :do hon.:dn cam. moaeo : :nmh. mco:.o mmo.o mac .uumou .uumoo .mmo mdoqw m c moco com mo ( O X 4 >x> fl- ... on: 3‘X>- ”0.. ‘.§ Zaox>x>>NN ~1d<<¢¢xx> HGuVHX>TfT "NNQDTTDDS Howdflzjmmm Zh-LDLDMU) u u M DVdOOuu>NN NOZJJX>XX> mnwmm O O M N REGAN290 FEGAN320 AND CROSS-PRODUCTS S - r- ‘- MODIFIED SUM OF SQUAR O O - V=SUMXIAN =$UMYIAN A YAV ALCULATE AVERAGES CQUWH£ALUHJI U C “05‘00‘ C 60 65 PT C) LDPE 6 AND INTERC tS SLOPE h RS(S GMT m NA m». c»- N: KC 70 75 mam uuqa m:.m«.ao. ~s\:~\mo .n. ou.xm.n. on. xm.-.xo._:. on o2m thm aaqu am am or 0c an o» oo.mm .cw. mmzH4qu 44:»; MH moan um XUMIQnofittp ~+mwzHaumwzH4 ow L mmwzsoo mzHJ .zmtumquos‘.5w aw. om.oo.az.uu 0 23¢ hm<4 you XUt wrotsotww . An. nu. xoa .xm :. Au .xm.m.~«¢.x~.n<.xnw.a7w.harmou a: mh.~m.¢ : m (.uoouao: hzwd z. whwuz u thDmmm wbuazototww a.aomUSmu>mmo.xxmmuo..wuz<.yhwcm :muw ..Nos. «.\..~a2¢..»ocm «um» c moamep