x .1 . =. E: u: ((53 J< 11.3.?! 3.7!.) (4‘. 2.12.... 3. {HG-.4: .3 .vrfuztii‘i. 2.2.2 w?t:<{£v.. 3.24, p = 5.23, p < .01), the rate of career advancement (i.e., the number of promotions per year, .43 > .31, p = 4.63, p < .01), and final performance ratings (i.e., the most recent performance ratings, 3.78 > 3.15, p = 9.76, p < .01) were significantly greater for stayers than for leavers. Dreher speculated that the performance differences between leavers and stayers could be 26 attributed to the company's policy and practice of rewarding superior performance. Since there is previous evidence (Dreher, 1977) validating the performance-reward relationship in this company, these data suggest that performance contingent promotional practices may contribute to functional turnover. Similarly, in a study of bank tellers where poorer performers quit more often than better performers, Stumpf and Dawley (1981) found that three measures of performance were negatively correlated with turnover: promotions (i.e., from teller trainee, to junior teller, to intermediate teller, and then to senior teller; p = -.33, from 1970- 1976; p - -.81 from 1977-1978), difference records (i.e., differences of over $1 in cash shortages or overages based on a teller's daily closing tally; ; = -.41, from 1970-1976; p = -.12 from 1977-1978); and annual supervisor ratings which were compiled into an overall global index of performance based on the employee's entire tenure (p = -.30, from 1970-1976; p = -.21 from 1977-1978). Stumpf and Dawley noted that during the 1970-1976 period, "If no improvement was made over a few months, the teller would be dismissed. As it became apparent to new tellers that this was bank policy, those with poor difference records (a performance measure) may have resigned before their situation resulted in dismissal" (pp. 160-161). These policies resulted in an increase in the relationship between performance and promotions (p = .30 for the 1970-76 group, and p =.46 for the 1977-78 group), suggesting that the employees learned that promotions were contingent on performance. The possible learning of this performance- promotion contingency may explain the strong relationship between promotions and staying on the job during 1977 and 1978. As in 27 Dreher’s (1977) study, these data point to the possibility of a positive relationship between reward contingency (promotions) and functional turnover. Research by Dansereau, Cashman, and Graen (1973) also addresses the important role that supervisors can have on functional turnover through tying rewards to performance and communicating this contingency to their subordinates. In this study, 261 managers from all departments of a large manufacturing corporation were separated into two groups on the basis of subordinate ratings of initiating structure on the Leadership Behavioral Description Questionnaire (Fleishman & Harris, 1962; Stogdill & Coons, 1957). Evidence from a previously published study (Graen, Dansereau & Minami, 1972) with this same data set indicated that subordinates working for managers who were either high or low on structure perceived a strong relationship between performance and rewards. However, subordinates who worked under managers who imposed only a moderate amount of structure (i.e., ambiguity) did not perceive rewards as related to performance. Consistent with the hypotheses presented here, turnover in the Dansereau et a1., (1973) study was functional under high-low structure leaders, as the standardized performance mean for leavers was -.34 versus .08 for stayers. The average annual salary was also lower ($455) for leavers than stayers. In contrast, turnover was dysfunctional under leaders who imposed moderate structure. Here, the standardized performance means were -.04 for stayers and .25 for leavers. The salary of the better performing leavers was significantly higher ($3394) than that of the lower performing stayers. 28 Finally, in a study of 420 entry level credit managers in a retail credit institution, Wells and Muchinsky (1985) found that promoted employees (N-140) performed significantly better on all 12 performance dimensions than did those who voluntarily left (n=l40) the organization, who in turn were better performers than those fired (N-140) from the organization (i.e., involuntary turnover). The authors strongly suggest that performance contingent reward practices existed in this organization by noting that, "It would be highly unusual for a successfully performing credit manager to remain at the entry-level management position for the balance of his or her career," (p. 330), "...as it is the "survivors" from this position that often rise to assume the most critical role for maintaining the profitability of the company, the job of branch manager," (p. 335). They concluded that the relationship between performance and turnover was "probably moderated by organizational practices that reward performance (or fail to do so)...," (p. 336). Therefore, both the results of this study and the conclusions drawn by its authors also tend to support the predictions of the entire model. Though not conclusive, the results of these four studies strongly suggest that performance contingent rewards can have a positive effect on functional turnover. Hypotheses Thus, based on expectancy theory, and the results of the research discussed in the literature review, the following hypotheses are advanced: 1) Objective reward contingency will have a positive direct relationship with perceived reward contingency. 2) 3) 4) 29 The relationship between performance and satisfaction is moderated by perceived reward contingency such that performance and satisfaction will have a stronger positive relationship under conditions of higher perceived reward contingency than in conditions of perceived lower reward contingency where the relationship will be weaker. The effects of objective reward contingency and perceived reward contingency on functional turnover will be mediated through pay satisfaction and job satisfaction. If perceived reward contingency moderates the relationship between performance and satisfaction, there will be significant pay satisfaction and job satisfaction differences across the four functional turnover groups. .‘fl L CHAPTER THREE METHOD Sample and Procedure This study used a nonequivalent control group design where four separate companies represented four different levels of objective reward contingency, ranging from straight commission and no salary to mostly salary plus small commissions/bonuses. While not a true field experiment, the design can be viewed as a "natural experiment" (Cook & Campbell, 1979, p. 296) because sampling from companies with different levels of reward contingency approximated the design--though not the control-~of a field experiment in which levels of reward contingency were systematically varied. Indeed, one consequence of this design is that organization is fully confounded with objective reward contingency. Consequently, although these organizations were chosen precisely because they paid their sales representatives different combinations of salary and commissions, a number of other nonmeasured differences associated with organization could serve as alternative explanations for the results of this study. While this is surely a design limitation, the difficulty of conducting a controlled field experiment on this topic, rather than a field study, should also be recognized. To conduct a true field experiment, one would have to (a) find a company willing to allow the researcher to change the pay reward contingency for half of its sales 30 31 representatives, or (b) find a company that has two groups of employees performing identical jobs under identical situations that then pays those two groups using different levels of reward contingency, and, furthermore, is willing to participate in research. Company A is a manufacturer and distributor of different kinds of filters and filtering processes and sells these products in industrial, medical and environmental markets. The sales staff (n = 22), which sells products in all three markets, is paid a salary plus commission. Commission is distributed quarterly and is paid for achieving a percentage of one’s annual cumulative quota. For example, at three months the goal is 22% of annual quota, continuing to 46% at six months, 72% at nine, and 100% of quota at twelve months. For the full year, sales representatives who achieve 125% of quota can earn a maximum of $23,000 of incentive pay. Other representative payouts are as follows: $17,000 at 115%, $11,000 at 105%, $8,000 at 100%, $4,000 at 95%, and $1,500 at 90%, the minimum payout. Overall in Company A, only 7% of total pay (figured in months, x = $3,253, s.d. = $605) came from bonuses (x = $227, s.d. = $140), while 93% came from salary (x = $3,026, s.d. = $711). Company B manufactures and sells office furniture products, ranging from chairs and smaller open office systems to fully integrated office systems. The sales staff (n = 58) is paid on a three-tier salary scale ($24,000, $28,000, and $32,000), plus commissions, which are paid quarterly. Commission based pay starts at 80% of quarterly quota, and is paid as follows: 1.5% for 80-90% of quota, 3% for 90-100% of quota, 2.3% for 100-200% of quota, 2% for 120-160% of quota and 1.5% for anything over 160% of quota. On 32 average for Company B, 27% of total pay (figured in months, x = $4,027, s.d. = $1,820) came from bonuses (x = $1,383, s.d. = $1,471), while 73% came from salary (x = $2,644, s.d. = $647). Company C manufactures, sells, and distributes conveyor equipment ranging from gravity rollers to overhead powered chain conveyors. These products are sold as components, many of which are smaller and mobile, and as specialized packages for industrial customers. Sales representatives (n = 42) are compensated on a three- level salary plus commission system. Under level 1, new recruits are not assigned a sales territory. Instead, they acquire product knowledge through in¥house training. Level 1 pays a salary, but no commission. There were no level 1 sales representatives in the study. At level 2, salaries range from $19,000 to $30,000. Commissions, which are paid monthly, are based on 2% of the first $400,000 in sales, 3% of the next $200,000, and 4% of all sales over $600,000. Schedule 3 is the same as schedule 2, but adds a year-end volume bonus and bonus credit. Volume bonuses are $3,000 for sales over $1,000,000 and $3,000 for each additional $500,000 in sales. Finally, above $2,000,000, $3,000 is awarded for each million in sales. Amounts between these levels are interpolated. Bonus credit is based on assigned margin, which is the percentage profit before taxes less all costs of a sale, in other words, the percentage profit cleared by the company on sales. Bonus credit for assigned margin bonus starts at $2,000 for 10% margin, with the addition of $500 for each 1% increase (for example, from 10% to 11%) in margin. Assigned margin bonuses are paid at the end of the year on accumulated margin for the year. On average in Company C, 64% Of total pay (figured in months, x = $4,986, 33 s.d. - $1,991) came from bonuses (x = $3,178, s.d. = $2,041), while only 36% came from salary (x = $1,808, s.d. = $204). Company D is a manufacturer and distributor of computerized automobile engine analyzers which are used to troubleshoot engine problems and/or evaluate engine exhaust emissions. The sales staff (n = 334) typically sells its products to independent service stations and garages. Sales representatives receive no salary and no bonuses. They are paid on straight commission (figured in months, x = $2,434, s.d. - $1,394) which, though it varies by product, is typically 10% of the product price after subtracting product trade allowance. Trade allowance, which can vary from 10 to 20%, represents the "slack" that representatives have in negotiating price with customers. Thus, sales representatives can cut list price from 10 to 20%, depending on the product and customer demands. However, if sales representatives can get the customer to pay more for the product by taking a smaller trade allowance, they then receive a larger commission. Questionnaire packets containing a cover letter from the researcher, a cover letter from the company, a questionnaire, and a stamped, addressed envelope which was to be used to mail the questionnaire directly to the researcher, were distributed to sales representatives by the personnel departments of each company in June 1986. A second questionnaire packet was mailed directly to each sales representative if the initial questionnaire was not returned within a month. Finally, a third and last questionnaire packet was sent if the second questionnaire had not been returned within a month of the second letter. Note that follow-up questionnaire packets were not sent to non-responders in company D because of the cost of sending 34 additional questionnaires to such a large sales force, and because a satisfactory number of questionnaires was projected to be returned, even with a potentially low response rate. Approximately 90% of the returned questionnaires were received within 6 weeks of the initial mailing. The response rates for each company were 9 of 22 (41%) for company A, 30 of 58 (52%) for company B, 21 of 42 (50%) for company C, and 75 of 334 (22%) for company D. Thus, the lower overall response rate (31%, 135 of 435) is primarily attributable to the lower response rate in company D, which was not unexpected since only one round of questionnaires was mailed to its sales representatives. Multivariate analysis of variance, which was used to compare responders and non-responders, indicated no significant differences in turnover, tenure, performance, total compensation, reward contingency, or gender in companies A, B, and C. However, in Company D, there were differences between responders and nonresponders, multivariate E (5, 242) - 3.68, p g .01. Follow-up univariate analyses indicated no significant differences in turnover, performance, gender, or reward contingency, though there were significant differences between responders and nonresponders in tenure (13 months versus 11 months, F (1, 246) = 8.46, p < .01), and in average total monthly compensation ($2,364 versus $1803, F (1, 246) = 8.97, p < .01). Missing data reduced the final, usable sample from 135 to 98. A total of 45 participants, 8 from Company A, 20 from Company B, and 17 from Company C, were paid according to some salary plus commission/bonus system. The remaining 53 participants, all from Company D, were paid straight commission. The average age was 37, 35 while the average tenure was 5 years. Eighty-seven (89%) of the participants were male, and 24 (24%) of the participants had quit their jobs. Approximately 6.2% possessed a master’s degree, 14.2% had some graduate school, 42.9% had graduated college, and 31.6% had some college, while the remaining 5.1% had only graduated high school. Measures Performance. The first step in constructing performance measures was to standardize performance within each company to remove level (i.e., mean) and dispersion (i.e., variance) differences in performance across companies. Performance was standardized by month within each company, and these standardized monthly scores were then averaged to create the measures of individual performance. (While standardization typically produces a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of l, the performance measures used in this study will vary somewhat from these levels because the sample used in the study is not the same as the entire "monthly population" of sale representatives -- which itself varied by month due to hires and turnover-- on which monthly means and standard deviations were figured). Standardization was necessary because it is misleading to compare individual sales performance across companies using raw sales performance. For example, raw performance data might indicate that the average sales person for Company C ($164,000 per month) is a better sales representative than the average sales representative for Company A ($61,000), when in fact this difference was due to differences in prices of products or general industry factors (i.e. ) level of competition, the economic cycle of the industry, and so on). 36 Thus, performance scores were standardized to create comparable measures of performance across companies. The second step was to partition performance into two distinct measures, past performance and overall performance. Pa§p_p§pfppmappg, performance data collected before questionnaire administration, was used to test the moderating effect of perceived reward contingency on the relationship between performance and satisfaction. Past performance was simply the average of standardized, monthly performance for each sales representative from April to June 1986. (Thus, sales representatives hired after April 1986 were excluded from the study since they would be lacking the required three months of sales data.) Unfortunately, the internal consistency reliability of this measure was low (a = .44) due to the instability of performance from month to month. Companies A, B, and D, however, provided measures of cumulative sales that could be used to increase the reliability of past performance. For Companies B and D, this meant an additional 3 months of data, including January, February, and March of 1986. Company A, which was on a July to June fiscal year, provided cumulative data back to July 1985. Cumulative sales were then divided by the appropriate number of "cumulative months," after adjusting for each employee’s starting date, to produce a "monthly average" for cumulative sales. This monthly average was standardized, like other monthly performance measures, and added to monthly sales for April, May and June, producing a total of four "months" of sales data, which was divided by 4 resulting in a measure of overall, average, monthly past performance. The addition of average, monthly cumulative sales 37 increased the average month-to-month correlation to .26 (p g .05), and internal consistency reliability to .58. However, the a of .58 is probably an underestimate because treating cumulative sales as a fourth month leads to a lower reliability than what would have been estimated had a been computed using six separate, disaggregated months of data in companies B and D, and 12 separate, disaggregated months of data in Company A. Qyppgll_pgg§ppmpppg, which combined standardized past performance data with standardized monthly sales data obtained after administration of the questionnaire, was used to compute functional turnover scores. Unlike cumulative sales which was simply divided by "cumulative months" to produce an average, monthly figure (i e., essentially a fourth month of data on which to figure past performance), overall performance was computed by adding each extra month of standardized sales performance (up to the time of termination, or the end of the study) and dividing by the number of months of employment during this time. So, in contrast to past performance, overall performance could be based on as many as 24 months of performance (Company A), 18 months (Companies B and D), or 15 months (Company C), to as few as six months (the minimum), depending on when the employee quit. Like any summated measure or scale, the internal consistency reliability of future performance rose with the addition of each homogeneous item, or in this case, each additional month of data. The average reliability for future performance, sample weighting for months of employment (whether the employee quit and when), was .83. The average month-to-month correlation was .24 (p g .05). 38 Objective Reward Contingency. "Objective" reward contingency is the actual relationship between sales performance and pay within a company. Consistent with expectancy theory's (Vroom, 1964) definition of instrumentality as the link between levels of performance and levels of outcome, the observed correlation between individual pay and performance should be used to measure "objective" reward contingency in each organization. Further, the theoretically correct correlation is a within-person correlation (Mitchell, 1974), where the correlation is computed on an individual sales person's pay and performance over some time period. This is a more precise way to determine reward contingency because it can account for individual differences in the pay-performance relationship within an organization which might arise from bonuses for meeting one's sales quota or for changes in commission which arise after achieving a particular sales volume. Practical considerations, however, prevent the use of the within-person correlation as the measure of objective reward contingency. At best, the within person correlation between pay and overall performance would be based on 20 data points for Company A, 18 for Companies B and D, and 15 for Company C. At worst, it would be based on a minimum of six data points since the minimum requirement was six months of performance data. In any event, sampling error and the effects of outliers (particularly good or bad months of sales volume) would make the reliability and validity of a within-person correlation suspect. It would seem that the next most plausible measure of reward contingency is an across-person correlation between pay and performance. Although the across-person correlation cannot reflect 39 individual differences in actual reward contingency within an organization's compensation system, it would be computed on a sufficiently large sample in each company. The problem with this measure is that it is unlikely to reflect differences in reward contingency across companies. For example, the correlation between pay and performance will approach 1.00 in companies that pay sales representatives strictly on a commission basis. The same correlation, however, is likely to occur in companies that use salary plus commission pay plans. Because of the small variation in salary, which is primarily used to adequately cover sales representatives living costs, salary pay is effectively a constant in these companies. Yet, there is tremendous variation in commission and bonus pay because of their direct link to differences in individual performance. The result, due to covariation between commission/bonuses and performance, is twofold: a strong correlation between total pay and performance under salary plus compensation systems, and, an inability to reflect company differences in reward contingency. After converting the correlations to Fisher 2’ equivalents (Cohen & Cohen, 1983), comparisons revealed that the correlations between pay and performance for Companies B, C, and D were not significantly different from each other (; = .71 in Company B, p = .79 in Company C, and p = .76 in company D). Only Company A (p,= .10) was significantly different (p g .05) from the others. The measure used here, which does not suffer from these problems, is the percentage of total pay based on sales commissions and bonuses. For example, stronger reward contingency is evidenced when, on average for a sales force, a large percentage of total pay 40 comes from commissions and bonuses, while weaker reward contingency occurs when most of total pay comes from salary. This measure also captures individual differences in reward contingency within companies, which become especially important under salary plus commission/bonus pay plans as better performers, relative to poorer ones, get most of their take home pay from commissions and bonuses. The components used to figure objective reward contingency were monthly salary, and commissions and bonuses which were converted to monthly units to parallel salaries. Each of these monthly measures was then averaged to create the measure of objective reward contingency. This measure was computed by dividing the total of average monthly commissions + average monthly bonuses by the total of average monthly salary + average monthly commissions + average monthly bonuses. The resulting percentage served as the final measure of objective reward contingency. Perceived Reward Contingency. Consistent with Vroom's (1964) original formulation of expectancy theory as a within-person model, theoretically correct measurement of instrumentality requires that participants rate the relationship between multiple levels of performance and multiple levels of pay. The measure of instrumentality used here was developed by Ilgen, Nebeker and Pritchard (1981) in an experimental work simulation designed to determine the reliability and validity of traditional and newly developed measures of expectancy theory constructs. Their study examined both the item format (e g., the wording of items: frequency, verbal anchors, probabilities, and correlational format) and the composite index (e.g., the way in which expectancy theory component 41 measures were combined to produce an overall composite measure of motivation: expected value index or correlation index) of expectancy theory measures. The item format selected for use in the present study was the probabilities format, using the correlation composite. A 2 x 2 analysis of variance for 2 levels of instrumentality (hourly pay versus contingent pay) and 2 levels of expectancy (low and high, manipulated by increasing work load) indicated strong validity for this format (E - 1.27 x 10, p < .001, omega squared = 1.00). Moreover, Ilgen et. al. found this format to have high test-retest reliability. When modified for the sales representatives in this study, this item read: "Using the following scale, rate each item by placing a number between 0 and 100 on each line such that the lines in one row add to 100." Chances in 100 of Getting this Annual Pay No A Slight A Fifty-Fifty A Good Certain This Chance Chance Chance Chance Will Happen (0) (25) (50) (75) (100) 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 8O 90 100 If your sales performance for the year totalled $ , what would be your chances of earning an annual income of ....... $00.00 $-2 s.d. $-1 s.d. $X $1 s.d. $2 s.d. per per per per per per year year year year year year + + + + + = 100" It should be noted that participants were asked to rate their chances of receiving six levels pf annual pay, starting with no pay to 42 differentiate sales staffs on straight commission from those on salary plus commission, and proceeding to five more levels of annual pay corresponding to the dollar level of annual pay for two standard deviations below the mean, one standard deviation below the mean, average pay, one standard deviation above the mean and two standard deviations above the mean of annual pay for that company. The use of these normative levels of pay within each company should result in participants rating levels of pay which are meaningfully equivalent (low, average or high) across companies. Participants completed this item (rating their chances of receiving six levels of annual pay) for pix levels pf annual sales performance, starting with no sales ($0.00) to differentiate sales staffs on straight commission from those on salary plus commission, proceeding to five levels which correspond to the dollar level of sales performance for two standard deviations below the mean, one standard deviation below the mean, average performance, one standard deviation above the mean and two standard deviations above the mean for annual sales performance in that company. As with pay, the use of normative levels of raw performance within each company should result in participants rating levels of performance which are meaningfully equivalent (low, average or high) across companies. Participant responses on the six instrumentality items were combined to form a six by six matrix where the rows represented levels of pay and the columns represented levels of performance. The entries in each cell of the matrix were composed of the participant's perceived probability of receiving that level of pay (row) at that level of performance (column). The values in this matrix, which 43 essentially constitute a scatterplot of the perceived relationship between pay and performance, were treated as frequencies in a bivariate distribution. A within-person correlation coefficient was then "calculated between the two dimensions in this two-dimensional space," (Ilgen, Pritchard, Dugoni, & Nebeker, 1980). Finally, the within person correlations were transformed to Fisher's z' scores to normalize the distribution of coefficients and satisfy equal variance assumptions for data analysis (Cohen & Cohen, 1983, p. 271). This final index, as represented by Fisher’s 2', represented the degree of perceived linear covariation between pay and performance. Pay Satisfaction. The pay satisfaction scale of the Job Descriptive Index (Smith, Kendall, & Hulin, 1969) was used to measure satisfaction with pay. Evidence of the JDI's reliability, and convergent and discriminant validity can be found in Johnson, Smith, and Tucker (1982). Responses were made using the conventional JDI format: "Y" for yes was coded 3, "N" for no was coded 0, and "?" for uncertain was coded 1 (Smith, Budzeika, Edwards, Johnson, & Bearse, 1986). Pay satisfaction was standardized within each organization. Internal consistency reliability for this scale was .81. Job Satisfaction. Hoppock's (1935) four item scale was used to measure overall job satisfaction. There are seven alternatives for each item (scores range from 4 to 28) and participants were instructed to choose one of the seven responses in each item. Internal consistency reliabilities for this measure have been acceptable, ranging from .76 to .89 on a total of 30,000 (McNichols, Stahl, & Manley, 1978), to as high as .93 (Hoppock, 1935). There is also support for the construct validity of this measure. McNichols e1. 44 al., also report that the scale is positively correlated (r = .73) with the work satisfaction scale of the Job Descriptive Inventory, and a measure of intention to remain in the military (; = .40). Dunham and Herman (1975) report a correlation of .75 with either the female faces scale, which Dunham and Herman published, or the original male faces scale published by Kunin (1955). Job satisfaction was standardized within each organization. Coefficient alpha was .80. Functional Turnover. Functional turnover represents the opportunity performance costs and gains associated with employee turnover and was computed as follows (Hollenbeck & Williams, 1986). Functional Turnover = Zi x T.0. where, Zi - individual overall sales performance standardized within each company, and T.0. = turnover, stays (coded +1) or leaves (coded -1). Turnover data were obtained in July 1987, one year after administration of the questionnaire. Participants who were terminated, retired, or transferred to a different position within the company were eliminated from analysis. Computed this way, functional turnover fully captures opportunity gains and losses because it combines z-scores, which compare individual performance to average performance within each company, and employment status (stay/leave). It also correctly treats opportunity gains and losses as a continuous measure. For example, a functional turnover score of .50 is clearly a better opportunity gain than a functional turnover score of .10. 45 Yet despite the ability to measure opportunity gains and losses, continuous functional turnover scores suffer from two serious deficiencies at the individual level of analysis where the research goal is prediction and understanding of the different stay/leave choices made by good and poor performers. First, from the standpoint of prediction, most of the variance in the continuous functional turnover scores will result from variance in performance, rather than variance in turnover, because performance is multiplied by +1 or -1 when creating the composite score. Thus, it can be argued that functional turnover simply reflects performance, especially in situations where there is little turnover or extreme turnover (i.e., where all or nearly all cases are simply standardized performance scores multiplied by +1 or -l). The second problem is that any continuous functional turnover score can be interpreted two ways. To illustrate, an opportunity gain of .50 could result from retention of a good performer (+l)(.50), or the voluntary loss of a poor performer (-l)(-.50). Therefore, continuous functional turnover scores must be disaggregated to determine the kind of opportunity gain or loss, that is, whether someone leaves or stays and whether they were a good performer or a poor performer. As a result, the continuous measure of functional turnover actually cancels out individual differences in performance and turnover. This happens because good performers are paired with poor performers, while stayers are combined with leavers (i.e, opportunity gains consist of poor performing leavers and good performing stayer; opportunity losses consist of good performing leavers and poor 46 performing stayers). Consequently, there can be no straightforward interpretation of continuous functional turnover scores at the individual level of analysis. Because of these problems, functional turnover was treated as a categorical variable to be able to differentiate between each of the four different kinds of functional turnover, and to account for the different antecedents associated with membership in each of those groups. Four groups were created by separating stayers and leavers into above average performers and below average performers. Poor performing leavers (n = 10) were coded 1, good performing leavers (n = 14) were coded 2, poor performing stayers (n = 28) were coded 3, and good performing stayers (n = 46) were coded 4. Data Analysis, Power Analysis, Restatement of Hypotheses Explanation of the data analysis proceeds in four steps: nonequivalent control groups, study design, hypothesis testing, and discriminant analysis. Nonequivalent control groups. One of the threats, among others, to the internal validity of quasi-experimental designs is the nonequivalence of groups across treatment conditions. In this study, preexisting differences between the sales representatives in each organization could contaminate comparisons across levels of reward contingency and pose an alternative explanation for study results. Because of its advantage in handling "unequal cell frequencies" (Cohen & Cohen, 1983), regression analysis will be used to conduct orthogonal contrasts for group differences in age, gender, education, and tenure across organizations (i e., different levels of reward contingency). 47 Since it was impossible to eliminate potential, measured differences a priori, they will be controlled statistically by entering them as covariates in all analyses. Study design. As a "natural experiment," each organization was to have represented a different level of "naturally" occurring objective reward contingency, which in turn was to be related to different levels of perceived reward contingency across organizations. Additional support for the study design would also be evident if perceived reward contingency moderated the relationship between past performance and job satisfaction, and past performance and pay satisfaction. Stated as null hypotheses: 1) There will be no differences in objective reward contingency across organizations. 2) There will be no differences in perceived reward contingency across organizations. 3) Objective reward contingency will not be positively related to perceived reward contingency. 4) The relationship between past performance and satisfaction (pay and job) will be invariant (i.e. not moderate) and not significantly different from zero across levels of perceived reward contingency. ’ Regression will be used to conduct orthogonal contrasts for mean differences on objective reward contingency (hypothesis 1) and perceived reward contingency (hypothesis 2) across companies (Cohen & Cohen, 1983). A directional t-test will be used to determine if the partial correlation between objective reward contingency and perceived reward contingency is significantly different from zero and positive (hypothesis 3). Using moderated regression (Saunders, 1956; Stone & Hollenbeck, 1985; Zedeck, 1971), satisfaction (pay and job) will be regressed on 48 the past performance (PP) and perceived reward contingency (PRC) main effects, followed by the PP x PRC interaction (hypothesis 4). If the addition of the cross-product term at step 2 results in a significant increase in R2, then the existence of the PP x PRC interaction will be confirmed. Since this is a directional hypothesis, the interaction, if significant, will be plotted to assess the predicted nature of the interaction. Based on already existing research (Cherrington et a1., 1971; Greene, 1973; Iaffaldano & Muchinsky, 1985; Mitchell, 1974; Vroom, 1964), it was estimated that the population R2 for satisfaction would be around .20 and that the double interaction would account for an incremental R2 of .05. The power for 98 subjects was .68, which is slightly lower than the recommended level of .80 (Cohen & Cohen, 1983). Hypothesis testing. Each of the hypotheses related to model testing is restated as null hypotheses below, followed by the procedure used to test it, and a power analysis indicating the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis given a final sample size of 98. 5) The effects of objective reward contingency and perceived reward contingency on functional turnover will not be mediated by pay satisfaction and job satisfaction. 6) The effect of performance on satisfaction will not be moderated by perceived reward contingency. That is, there will be no significant pay satisfaction and job satisfaction differences across the four functional turnover groups. According to James & Brett (1982), mediation models take the form x-->m-->y where "x has a direct effect on m, m has a direct effect on y, and x is not related directly to y when m is held 49 constant," (p. 308). In the present model, all the antecedents to pay satisfaction and job satisfaction may be categorized as x, pay satisfaction and job satisfaction as m the mediators, and functional turnover as y, the dependent variable. Following James & Brett (1982), a hierarchical analysis will be used to test this hypothesis. Pay satisfaction and job satisfaction will be entered in the hierarchical step before perceived and objective reward contingency. If pay satisfaction and/or job satisfaction mediate the effects of these variables on functional turnover, then pay satisfaction and job satisfaction will account for significant variance in functional turnover in the preceding hierarchical step (hypothesis 6), and, the incremental variance from adding the additional variables in the following hierarchical step will be statistically insignificant (hypothesis 5). Given a sample of 98, an a =.05, and an expected R2 of .10 for functional turnover, and with pay satisfaction and job satisfaction expected to account for almost all of that variance (say 9%) because of their role as mediators, the power to test these hypotheses is .87. Discriminant analysis. Testing of hypotheses 5 and 6 is conducted using hierarchical multivariate discriminant analysis because 1) the covariates (i.e., age, gender, education, and tenure), response variables (i.e, pay satisfaction and job satisfaction), and design variables (objective reward contingency--bonus pay after partialling total pay-~and perceived reward contingency) are likely to be intercorrelated, and 2) functional turnover is a categorical variable. More specifically, a hierarchical discriminant analysis is used 50 to test hypotheses 5 and 6. The measured covariates (i.e., age, tenure, education, and gender) will be entered in step 1, followed in step 2 where job satisfaction and pay satisfaction are entered to test their effects as mediators, followed by the design variables (i.e., total compensation, bonuses/commissions, and perceived reward contingency) in the last step. The canonical R and Wilks lambda, both of which are measures of overall level of discriminatory power, as well as the chi—squared test of significance will be reported for each hierarchical step. Interpretation of the unique contribution of each variable to group separation, assuming overall significance, will be judged using structure coefficients (Huberty, 1984; Huberty & Morris, 1989). Structure coefficients, which are analogous to factor loadings in factor analysis, indicate the correlation between the original variable and the linear discriminant function which maximizes group separation. The greater the greater the structure coefficient, the more an individual variable contributes to group separation. If the multivariate analysis indicates significant group separation, follow up orthogonal mean contrasts between groups will be conducted on those variables which had significant univariate effects. Finally, the results of the discriminant analysis will be corroborated by using the resulting linear classification function coefficients to assess the accuracy (i.e., hit rates) with which sales representatives can be correctly classified into each of the four functional turnover groups. The classification analysis will be adjusted for differences in group sizes (i e., priors = size) and will be tested for significance using the proportional chance criterion (Huberty, 1984). 51 CHAPTER FOUR RESULTS Descriptive Statistics Table 2 presents the means and standard deviations for each company and for the final sample of 98. Nonequivalent control groups. Orthogonal contrasts revealed preexisting differences in gender, education, and tenure, but not age, between sales representatives in each organization. Companies A and B had more female sales representatives than companies C and D. The sales staffs of companies A, B, and C typically had a college degree or some graduate school, while the staff of company D was more likely to have had only some college. Company C was characterized by significantly higher tenure than any other company, followed by Company B, which had tenure significantly higher than Companies A and D, who had the lowest tenure. Additional between company contrasts indicated no differences in pay satisfaction or job satisfaction, whether standardized or unstandardized. (Although both the standardized and unstandardized measures of pay satisfaction and job satisfaction are reported in Table 2, the standardized form of these measures will be used in subsequent analyses, as described in the methods section). In terms of performance, there were two differences. Company A sales representatives had a significantly lower level of past performance 52 53 Table 2: Descriptive Statistics by Organization and for the Final Sample. Variables Final Company Company Company Company Sample A B C D N 98 8 20 17 53 Age 14 37.13 32.25 34.60 36.59 39.00 §Q 8.39 5.75 8.63 8.01 8.37 Gender1 Males 87 4c,d 14¢,d 173.13 528,b Females 11 4 6 0 1 M .11 .50 .30 0.00 .02 SD .32 .54 .47 0.00 .14 Education2 g 3.85 4.63d 4.40cl 4.06d 3.45%”):0 SD .95 1.06 .75 .75 .87 Tenure 11 5.02 3.131%0 7.4239d 10.46”,cl 2.65b'° SD 5.25 2.83 5.83 7.52 1.55 Average Salary3 M $1111 $3026b'c'd $2644a'°'d $18083'b'd $ 0000.13,. SD $1298 $ 711 $ 647 $ 204 $ 00.00 Average Commission“ M $2169 $ 2270'cl $1383“d $3178” $2434” §_ $1676 $ 140 $1471 $2041 $1394 Average Total5 Compensation L4 $3269 $3253c $4027d $4986a'd $24310“ §_ $1840 $ 605 $1820 $1991 $1394 Table 2 (cont’d.). 54 Variables Final Company Company Company Company Sample A B C D Objective Reward Contingency M .70 .07bvcvd .27“,d .5991"cl 1.003vb'c SD .37 .05 .21 .16 0.00 Perceived Reward Contingency m 1.65 1.24(1 1.24d 1.48(1 1.93”» SQ .51 .50 .37 .27 .46 Unstandardized Pay Satisfaction M 32.69 37.75 31.40 39.06 30.38 SQ 14.29 5.29 11.93 8.10 16.78 Unstandardized Job Satisfaction M 20.53 21.38 20.05 21.71 20.21 SD 3.09 1.85 2.52 2.09 3.60 Standardized Pay Satisfaction M .02 .18 -.03 .00 .01 SD .99 .89 1.02 1.05 1.00 Standardized Job Satisfaction M -.04 .03 .02 .07 -.10 SD .99 1.07 .93 .78 1.07 Past Performance 14 .16 -.43d .05 .01 .34a SD .67 .69 .75 .58 .61 55 Table 2 (cont'd.). Variables Final Company Company Sample A B Company C Company D Overall Performance .16 -.39b-‘='d .14a .67 .64 .66 IUHZ C1 Turnover Quit 74 0d 2d Stayed 24 8 18 Functional Turnover Number of Poor Performers Leavers 10 0 0 Stayers 28 5 10 Number of Good Performers Leavers 14 0 2 Stayers 46 3 8 .11a .29 17d 0 10 .18a .40 22a,b,c 31 12 25 1O-Male, l-Female. 2l-Some high school, 2=Graduated high school, 3=Some college, 4-Graduated college, 5=Some graduate school,6=Master’s degree, 7-M.D., Ph.D., or some other professional degree. 3Monthly salary. Does not include commissions. l'Average commissions, on a per month basis. include salaries. 5Average, monthly total compensation, salary commissions. aSignificantly different from Company A, p g bSignificantly different from Company B, p g °Significantly different from Company C, p g dSignificantly different from Company D, p 5 Does not plus .05. .05. .05. .05. 56 than the sales representatives in Company D. Similarly, Company A sales representatives' overall performance was significantly lower than the overall performance of sales representatives in Companies B, C, and D. It should be noted that these small performance differences are for the most part irrelevant, since the relevant performance comparison occurs within companies where individual sales performance is judged to be above or below average. In terms of turnover, there was one significant difference across companies. Company D experienced a much higher rate of turnover (42%) in the final sample than Company A (0%), Company B (10%), or Company C (0%). Although this level of turnover was consistent for Companies B and D which experienced turnover of 4% and 45% the previous year, much more turnover was expected in Companies A and C, both of which had 20% turnover in the previous year. Note that while turnover is not the dependent variable, this configuration of turnover across companies creates a pattern of functional turnover where all poor performing leavers and almost all the good performing leavers come from Company D. In contrast, poor performing stayers, as well as good performing stayers, come from all 4 companies in the sample. Indeed, a discriminant analysis using organization as the discriminating variables indicated significant overall differences (p g .0002) in functional turnover across organizations. These functional turnover differences will be discussed again in the context of hypothesis testing. Because almost all the turnover occurred in Company D, objective reward contingency is effectively a constant of 1.00 for all leavers, regardless of their performance. As such, objective reward 57 contingency, and the satisfaction differences predicted to be related to it, should be unable to differentiate poor performing leavers from good performing leavers. However, reward contingency might still uncover meaningful differences between each group of leavers and the good and poor performing stayers. Intercorrelations Among Study Variables. Table 3 shows the intercorrelations among study variables. As expected given the study design, objective reward contingency was negatively related to average salary (p - -.89, p g .05), and positively related to average commission (p = .46, p 3.05). Similarly, perceived reward contingency was negatively related to average salary (p = - 59, p g .05) and average total compensation (p = -.25, p g .05), and positively related to average commission (p = .18, p g .05) and objective reward contingency (; - .56, p g .05). Study Design Hypotheses Null Hypothesis 1: There will be no differences in objective reward contingency across organizations. Orthogonal contrasts indicated significant differences in average monthly salary, average commissions (averaged to a monthly interval), average monthly total compensation, and objective reward contingency between all companies, resulting in the rejection of null hypothesis 1. The between company contrasts of objective reward contingency were particularly important because they served as a check on the design strategy used in the study: "to gather data from sales forces working under different levels of reward contingency..". Company A, with the largest salary and smallest commissions had a reward contingency percentange of .09, followed by Company B, which 58 amopm u" HsfimHOOHHmHmdwonm manna mn;9<.838» .8» 1.8» 1.8 .8» 1.8 111 ooaawmm.o: 4. 509.6%» .8 .3 .8» .mm» .8» .13» 111 adflmH mm m. 03.89% .8» 1.3»1.3»1.8»1.8» .8»1.8 111 wmz. noun 6. 868434.84 .8» 1.8» 1.8» 1.8» 1.8» .8» 1.8» .8» 111 wmz. noun. » » » » 40.448.83.665 1.8 .8 .8 .8 .8 .8 .8 1.8 1.5 111 mmdwmmmnnwo: » » 489803.36 .8 .8 1.5 .8 .8 .5 .2 1.8 1.8 .8 111 mmflwmmmOHHomm 59 Hmowm u Aoo:d_a.v. <0Hmo0 gmmwosm‘ o: m 00H. Bond: gmwm 4 98.50 030810 0.89%. comm :00 8.0850 080300 . MOW/00000. 30:va dog 0960:8303. 0&3 E100 088M888 4 98% 05.9.5.0 000%. 3. 003,40 H053 0033:0050K 985 0308.0 005%. Mwmndmnzmn wmswa 00505038? mamamawmmm $35.5 096034.. olwuncfid‘ Hnmflmwma. 61 had significantly smaller salaries and larger commissions, and an objective reward contingency percentage of .27. (While it would appear that the commissions paid in Company B were significantly larger than those paid in company A, the larger mean and variance in Company B were due to an exceptional quarterly commission of $31,700 for one sales representative. The median commission of $350 in Company B is actually very similar to the average commission of $283 paid in Company A). Company C had smaller salaries than Company B, but had the largest commissions, and an objective reward contingency percentage of .59, followed finally by Company D, which paid no salary and 100% commissions. Null Hypothesis 2: There will be no differences in perceived reward contingency across organizations. Null hypothesis 2 was rejected as orthogonal between company contrasts explained 36% of the variance (2 3 .00001) in perceived reward contingency. These contrasts revealed a significant difference in perceived reward contingency between Company D, which paid straight commission and had the highest levels of perceived reward contingency, and companies A, B, and C, which paid salary plus commissions and had a lower level of perceived reward contingency. Even though null hypothesis 2 was rejected, it should be noted that the 2-way differences in perceived reward contingency did not fully complement the 4-way differences in objective reward contingency. The levels of perceived reward contingency were generally in the right direction, getting smaller with lower levels of objective reward contingency (A, 7% commission, PRC = 1.24; B, 27% commission, PRC = 1.24; C, 59% commission, PRC = 1.48), but were not 62 strong enough to produce more than a 2-way significant difference. The level of significance for these contrasts was A versus B, p g .98, A versus C, 2 g .19, and B versus C, p g .09. Since it is unlikely that the sales representatives in these companies were ignorant of how much of their pay came from salary or commissions, it may be that the nonsignificant differences in perceived reward contingency between Companies A, B, and C were due to the format of items used to tap these perceptions. Recall that participants were asked to rate their chances of receiving six levels of monthly pay ($0.00, $-2§Q, $-l§Q, $X, $+l§Q, $+2§Q) for each of six levels of monthly sales performance ($0.00, $-2§Q, $-1§Q, $X, $+l§Q, $+2§Q), such that within levels of performance the "chances of getting paid" added to 100. A sample item is shown below: 1) If your total annual sales performance was $960,000, what would be your chance (1 in 100) of getting paid ....... A) $ 000.00 per year ....... + B) $ 5,000.00 per year ....... + C) $25,000.00 per year ....... + D) $45,000.00 per year ....... + E) $65,000.00 per year ....... + F) $85,000.00 per year ....... + TOTAL- 100 However, it was very common for the "chances" within each level of performance to be distributed among just two or three levels of pay. For example, distributions of 50/50, 60/40, 70/30, and 80/20, or 50/40/10 and 65/25/10 were common. Often, though, participants simply shifted similar distributions "down the scale" when rating higher levels of annual sales performance. If the distribution for the above item was 0/0/50/50/0/0, many participants would shift the distribution to 0/0/0/50/50/0 for the next highest level of performance, resulting 63 in a close to linear progression between sales performance and the chance of getting paid a certain level of compensation. Table 4, which shows the mean response distributions by performance and pay level, demonstrates this "down the scale" effect for each company. Examination of Table 4 also reveals other notable differences. First, the perceived stability of pay across the first three levels of performance in Companies A and B, and the first two levels of performance in Company C, indicates that the salaries in those companies attenuate the perceived relationship between pay and performance at lower levels of performance, although not enough to significantly reduce the size of the perceived relationship between pay and performance across all six levels of pay and performance. In contrast at Company D, pay is strictly tied to performance at all levels of performance, even low performance. For example, if you don't sell at all in Company D, there is an 89% perceived chance that you’ll receive no pay, in comparison to a 32% chance in Company A, an 11% chance in Company B, and a 3% chance in Company C. In sum, this "down the scale" bias may have resulted in a spuriously high floor effect on the perceived correlation between pay and performance and thus reduced the chance of obtaining significant differences in perceived reward contingency across all four organizations. For comparative purposes, Figures 3 to 9 display the distribution of perceived reward contingency responses for each company in terms of correlations, and correlations converted to Fisher’s g', the latter serving as the measure used in the study. Null Hypothesis 3: Objective reward contingency will not be positively related to perceived reward contingency. Despite the lack of significant differences in perceived reward 64 Table 4: Mean Organizational Response Distributions for Perceived Reward Contingency by Performance Level and Pay Level Performance - Level $$ 0 4% -1§_ X +l§_ +2fl Chance (1 in 100) of §§ Compensation for SS Sales Performance: Pay Level Company A 1) 0 32 0 0 0 0 0 2) -2_Q 3 13 2 2 1 1 3) -1§Q 47 55 60 45 15 1 4) X 18 19 25 29 20 20 5) +1§Q 0 12 12 22 44 31 6) +2§_ 0 0 1 1 19 47 Company B 1) O 11 7 4 0 0 0 2) -2§Q 3 3 6 4 0 0 3) -1§Q 73 79 64 42 18 4 4) X 13 10 25 44 43 32 5) +1§D 0 0 l 8 32 34 6) +2§_ 0 0 0 3 8 30 Company C 1) 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 2) ~2§Q 4O 12 2 0 0 O 3) -1§Q_ 58 87 70 14 2 1 4) X 0 1 28 61 19 14 5) +1§Q 0 0 0 25 65 38 6) +2§_ 0 0 0 2 14 48 Company D 1) 0 89 50 2 1 0 0 2) -2§Q 5 44 23 1 0 1 3) -1§Q 3 4 67 32 4 1 4) X 2 1 6 44 34 13 5) +1§Q O 0 1 19 41 36 6) +2§_ 0 0 0 3 21 50 Frequency 65 Figure 2: Perceived Correlations Between Pay and Performance, Company A, n = 8 Perceived r's 66 Figure 3: Fisher's 2' Transformation of Perceived Correlations Between Pay and Performance, Company A, n =8 “33%“me flgwgflwfififiygfifimx .9 u an: :1" cc A u u. a a.€%%%fi§i%%fi§a§ ... Y833.”— o q /IIIIIA owmmvmmnmmPPvammmmmmwmmwmmmmmm v-v-v-v—v-v-r-v—v— NNNNNNNNN OOOOOOOOO Fisher's 2's Frequency A 67 Figure 4: Perceived Correlations Between Pay and Performance, Company B, n = 20 Perceived r's Frequency 68 Figure 5: Fisher's 2' Transformation of Perceived Correlations Between Pay and Performance, Company B, n = 20 A 1* I v v v or-Ncou-mcorxecc)..v-va-anorxcoanv—vamcorxcomm 000000000 Fv-v-v-v-v-v-v-v- NNNNNNNNN Fisher's 2's Frequency 69 Figure 6: Perceived Correlations Between Pay and Performance, Company C, n=17 8- 6- 4- 2.. O frrrlvt‘fil’v’fv omv—mwmmmvmmm QofoquoYou’. o o o o o o Perceived r's Frequency Figure 7: Fisher’s 2' Transformation of Perceived Correlations Between Pay and Performance, Company C, n = 17 r frrrrrtvvw O‘rvr.....rr r....... 000000000 v—v—v—v—v-v—v—v-v- NNNNNNNNN Fisher's z's 7] Figure 8: Perceived Correlations Between Pay and Performance, Company D, n = 53 50- Frequency om—mmmmmvmmmwmnmm ‘3 ai0“'7!0“:0“".0‘°.0".0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Perceived r's Frequency 72 Figure 9: Fisher's 2' Transformation of Perceived Correlations Between Pay and Performance, Company D, n = 53 Orr r ffrivllvffffivvvr rw—. ov—vamcotxcova—vaIntonaocan—wamcolxoomm 000000000 v-v—v-v-v-v-v—v-v- NNNNNNNNN F isher's z's 73 contingency across Companies A, B, and C, smaller levels of objective reward contingency were strongly associated with smaller perceived levels of reward contingency (partial p = .57, p g .05), leading to the rejection of null hypothesis 3. Null hypothesis 4: The relationship between past performance and satisfaction (pay and job) will be invariant (i.e., not moderate) and not significantly different from zero across levels of perceived reward contingency. Null hypothesis 4 was tested using moderated regression. The first step in the analysis removed the effects of the measured covariates, age, tenure, education, and gender. These variables are also commonly controlled for in analyses of pay satisfaction (Dyer & Theriault, 1976; Heneman, 1973; Hinrichs, 1969; Lawler, 1966; and Schwab, 1973). The main effects for past performance and perceived reward contingency were then entered in steps 2 and 3, with their interaction entered last. The results for standardized pay satisfaction appear in Table 5, while those for standardized job satisfaction are displayed in Table 6. Of the covariates, only age (ARZ== .05, p g .05) explained significant variance in standardized pay satisfaction. Past performance explained an additional 4 percent of the variance (p g .05) in standardized pay satisfaction; however, there was no evidence for a perceived reward contingency main effect (A32 = .00, pppp). The past performance (PP) by perceived reward contingency (PRC) was entered last in step 4, but was not significant. Parallel analyses regressing the same covariates, main effects, and interaction on standardized job satisfaction, none of which were significant, are shown in Table 6. 74 Table 5: Moderated Regression Analysis on Standardized Pay Satisfaction Hierarchical Step Variable R2 AR2 p of AR2 1 Age .05 g .05 .05 p g .05 Tenure .05 g .05 .00 n.s Education .05 g .05 .00 n.s Gender .00 g .05 .00 n.s 2 Past .09 g .05 .04 p g .05 Performance (PP) 3 Perceived .09 g .05 .00 n.s Reward Contingency (PRC) 4 PP x PRC .11 g .05 .02 n.s 75 Table 6: Moderated Regression Analysis on Standardized Job Satisfaction Hierarchical Step Variable R2 AR2 p of AR2 1 Age .00 .00 n.s Tenure .00 .00 n.s Education .00 .00 n.s Gender .00 .00 n.s 2 Past .00 .00 n.s Performance (PP) 3 Perceived .00 .00 n.s Reward Contingency (PRC) 4 PP x PRC .02 .02 n.s 76 Although null hypothesis 4 could not be rejected for either satisfaction measure, it is quite possible that standardizing job and pay satisfaction within companies biased the moderated regression analyses used to test this hypothesis. Arguments and evidence for this alternative perspective, that is, for standardizing the performance variables and for not standardizing the pay satisfaction and job satisfaction variables, are expressed next. Standardization. One of the primary uses of standardized scores is to allow comparison of measures with different metrics (Chiselli, Campbell, & Zedeck, 1981; Glass& Stanley, 1970). This is accomplished by subtracting the mean from each individual score and dividing by the standard deviation, (Xi- X)/S.D., which provides an index, in standard deviation units, of how far above or below the mean a score is. The resulting distribution of standard scores, regardless of the original metric and distribution, will have a mean of 0.00 and a standard deviation of 1.00. Because of the differences in raw sales performance measures across companies (i.e., different products, different prices for the products, and different industry factors), raw performance scores were standardized by month within each organization to facilitate comparison of individual sales performance across companies. Unlike the performance measures, which were not comparable, identical pay satisfaction and job satisfaction measures were used in each organization. Thus, the rationale for standardization of pay satisfaction and job satisfaction has to be different than that given for performance. It was argued (during discussion with the committee at the proposal stage) that standardizing performance without 77 standardizing satisfaction was wrong because between group (i.e., across company) differences would be removed for performance, but not for pay satisfaction and job satisfaction. No doubt, the basic premise of this argument is correct: variables involved in the same statistical analysis must be comparable in terms of between group variance (Sockloff, 1975). Furthermore, this consideration is not particular to the study of functional turnover. Indeed, McIntyre (1990) makes the same argument with respect to combining different data samples for criterion-related test validation. Likewise, Dreher, Ash, and Hancock (1988) expressed similar concerns about collapsing data across different interviewers when determining the validity of the employment interview. The basic issue in equating between group variance (i.e., or in deciding whether to standardize) is determining if the differences across groups are real or unreal Ghiselli et. a1., (1981, pp. 64-73). Real organization differences, referred to as legitimate mean differences by McIntyre (1990), arise from actual situational or dispositional differences in the mean and standard deviation of the variable being measured. For example: "Suppose we are measuring heights of school children and we take a random sample from each school in the city. For various reasons it may very well be that the average height of students from the various schools is actually different. The observed differences among the means of our sample are not due to sampling error and are not due to the fact that some schools measure height with a ruler that has 11 inches per foot and some do not. They are real: each school is drawing students from genuinely different subgroups," (Ghiselli et. a1., 1981, p. 73). In this example, standardization would produce the between groups variance problem discussed above because it would wipe out real 78 differences that exist between schools. In fact, McIntyre (1990, p. 91) suggests that when there are legitimate mean differences across subgroups, those differences "..do not represent a problem in the estimation of the validity coefficient." In contrast, unreal or spurious differences are caused by differences in measuring devices, or by rater errors (Dreher et a1., 1988; McIntyre, 1990). Ghiselli et a1. (1981) offer another example: "Suppose we learn that Jason received the raw scores of 45 on an arithmetic test and 72 on a history test. 0n the other hand, Cindy, who is in another class, received a 39 on arithmetic and an 80 on history. What kinds of between- or within-person comparisons can be made? Not many unless we convert to z or T scores. We obtain the means and s.d.’s for Jason's two classes and also for Cindy's two classes, and conversions to T scores provide the following: Jason has T scores of 40 and 64 on arithmetic and history, respectively, whereas Cindy has 50 and 51, respectively. The comparisons we can make are as follows: First, Jason is doing better in history than in arithmetic relative to other students’ performance in each of those classes. He is below average in arithmetic but above average in history. Likewise, Cindy is above average, and equal, in her performance in history and arithmetic. Second, compared to other students in Cindyis arithmetic class, she is better in arithmetic than is Jason. The reverse is true for history. None of these comparisons can be made if we only have raw scores (italics added)," (p. 68). Standardization is appropriate in this latter example because the differences are metric differences, not real ones. In other words, equivalence in between group variance becomes a concern only if standardization removes "real" group differences. Given these guidelines, it would seem that differences in sales performance across organizations are not real differences but metric differences produced by differences in the product, the cost of the product, etc. And, if the performance differences were not real differences, then standardization would not remove real between group 79 variance. Consequently when performance is standardized, there would be no need to also standardize pay satisfaction and job satisfaction to ensure equivalence in between group variance. The most direct evidence on this issue is the raw sales performance data in each company. For example, the average monthly performance and standard deviation were $60,690 and $29,753 for company A, $126,799 and $214,463 for company B, $82,657 and $164,104 for Company C, and $13,223 and $20,261 for Company D. Any analysis based on these numbers would be misleading because some of the best performers in Company D, which has the lowest dollar sales, would be treated as poor performers when compared with the much higher dollar sales of representatives in Companies A, B, and C. To illustrate, recall that standardized past performance was negatively related (; - -.34) to salary, but positively related (3 = .40) to commissions, and total compensation (p = .11). These numbers made sense because when sales performance increased, any increase in total pay came from commissions, hence their strong positive relationship with performance. It did not come from salary, which was generally unchanged from month to month. Indeed, it was the lack of variability in salary which attenuated the correlation of average total compensation (salary + bonuses) from that of commissions. In comparison, the correlations with unstandardized performance are .33 for bonuses, .52 for total compensation, and .41 for average monthly salary which, contrary to the correlations with standardized performance, suggests that total compensation is more strongly related to performance than bonuses, and that salary actually increases with performance. In fact, these spurious correlations occur because the 80 sales representatives in Company D, who also have the lowest dollar sales, were only paid commission and received no salary, whereas the remaining sales representatives all have larger dollar sales and received regular monthly salaries. Again, these results seem to indicate that the differences in performance across organizations are nothing but scale differences. A second consideration in determining the threat of "real differences" is the purpose of each part of the data analysis. If the purpose was to determine the effect of higher levels of reward contingency (across companies) on performance, standardization of performance would be inappropriate because it would remove the effect of objective reward contingency on performance (i.e., real differences). However, this is not the purpose as neither the moderated regression analysis, nor the discriminant analysis, nor the functional turnover variable itself involves a comparison of absolute performance across companies. According to Stone and Hollenbeck (1984), "One variable (e.g., z) is said to moderate the relationship between two other variables (e.g., x and y) if the degree of association between x and y varies as a function of the value assumed by z . . .," (p. 196). Given that hypothesis 4 predicts that perceived reward contingency (2) will moderate the relationship between past performance (x) and satisfaction (y), standardization of performance within organizations would produce an inappropriate test of this hypothesis only if it changed the relationship between performance and satisfaction as it exists within each level of objective reward contingency. But, since standard scores are perfectly correlated with raw scores with 81 organizations, changing raw scores to standard scores will not change an individual's rank order on performance or the shape of the distribution of performance scores within each organization or level of reward contingency. And, it is the change in the correlation between performance and satisfaction across levels of perceived reward contingency that was being investigated in the moderated regression: absolute differences in performance were not of interest. Similarly with the discriminant analysis and functional turnover, absolute levels of performance were not considered. Instead, individual performance was relative to average performance within each company. Thus, the performance comparison is not across companies (or levels of reward contingency), but within companies. Because standardization occurs within levels of reward contingency (i.e., organizations), it should be recognized that reward contingency is a constant for each individual performer. And, as a constant within that organization/level of reward contingency, reward contingency does not affect the relative performance difference between individual performance and average performance. Note, however, that the absolute magnitude of this difference across companies will not be comparable in raw performance scores because of differences in product prices, etc. All standardization does is ensure the comparability of functional turnover across organizations by removing the level and dispersion differences caused by these factors. Functional turnover scores become comparable across companies because they are now stated in standard deviations units which preserve the within company comparison of average performance to the performance of stayers and leavers. 82 For example, assume that in Company Q, X = $1,000,000 and s.d. = $200,000, and that in Company 2, X = $600,000 and s.d. = $100,000. Also, assume that two exemplary salespeople (+3 s.d.'s; $1,600,000 in Company Q, and $900,000 in Company Z) have decided to leave. Using raw performance, the functional turnover score for the Company Q sales representative is $-600,000 (-1 x ($1,600,000 - $1,000,000)) and $—300,000 for the Company Z sales representative (-1 x ($900,000 - $600,000)). Thus, using raw performance it appears that flow is twice as bad in this instance for Company Q as it is for Company Z. If we were determining the utility of functional turnover, this would be the proper conclusion. We know, however, from earlier discussion, that functional turnover is concerned with relative performance, not absolute performance, and that the absolute difference in the Company Q and Company Z functional turnover scores is due to differences in products they sell. In relative terms, not the absolute utility of functional turnover, Company Q and Company Z experience identical consequences when these individuals leave. Both companies lose salespeople 3 s.d.'s above the mean. Standardization equalizes these differences by ensuring the comparability of these deviation scores in terms of level and dispersion. Thus, after standardization, functional turnover for the sales representative in Company Q is -3.0 (-1 x +3), the same as it is for the sales representative in Company Z (-1 x +3). To summarize, if the performance differences across organizations are not real differences, and if the moderated regression analysis and the functional turnover variable rely on 83 within organization relationships and comparisons, then standardization of performance does not remove real between group variance. Thus, based on the rationale that "variables involved in the same statistical analysis must be comparable in terms of between group variance," there would be no need to standardize pay satisfaction and job satisfaction to ensure equivalence in between group variance when it already existed. In fact, standardization probably accomplishes just the opposite by removing real organization differences in pay satisfaction and job satisfaction across companies. While standardization did not remove any significant level effects, as evidenced by nonsignificant mean differences in either satisfaction variable across organizations, in all likelihood it probably removed real differences in the range and variance of satisfaction across organizations. For example, the standard deviation of pay satisfaction for Company D (s.d. = 16.78) is significantly larger than the standard deviations for Company A (s.d. 5.29; Cochran's C (30,2) = .91, p g .000; Bartlett-Box F (1,1282) = \0 .13, p g .003), Company B (s.d. = 11.93; Cochran’s C (36,2) = .66, p IA .044; Bartlett-Box F (1,8088) = 2.83, p g .093), and Company C (s.d. 8 10; Cochran's C (34,2) = .81, p g .000; Bartlett—Box F (1,6010) = 9.58, p g .002). These variance differences are real differences which generally can be predicted by the level of reward contingency and the variance in pay in each company. For example, the standard deviation for pay satisfaction should be extreme in Company D because the affective range of pay is extreme. That is, if you sell, you earn commissions, and you’re more satisfied with your pay. If you don’t sell, you don’t 84 earn any commissions, and ought to be very dissatisfied. The somewhat smaller standard deviations in Companies B and C can be attributed to the floor effect of reward contingency as all B and C sales representatives receive a monthly salary regardless of sales performance. Similarly, the smallest standard deviation in pay satisfaction occurs in company A which pays a monthly salary, and has the lowest level of reward contingency and the smallest range in bonuses and total pay. Finally, by removing the variance differences in pay satisfaction and job satisfaction across organizations, standardization artifactually creates a restriction in range which will generally attenuate correlations with other variables. For example, the unstandardized and standardized correlations for pay satisfaction shrink, respectively, from .15 to .00 with salary, from .20 to .15 with bonuses, and from .27 to .14 with total compensation. In conclusion, the alternative perspective is that it is appropriate to standardize performance without standardizing pay satisfaction and job satisfaction because standardizing performance removes metric differences while standardizing job satisfaction and pay satisfaction would remove real between group differences. Null hypothesis 4, unstandardized job satisfaction and unstandardized pay satisfaction: The relationship between past performance and unstandardized satisfaction (pay and job) will be invariant (i.e., not moderate) and not significantly different from zero across levels of perceived reward contingency. The results of the moderated regression analysis using unstandardized pay satisfaction appear in Table 7. Both age (ARZ== .05, p g .05) and tenure (ARZ== .06, p g .05) explained 11% of the 85 Table 7: Moderated Regression Analysis on Unstandardized Pay Satisfaction Hierarchical Step Variable R2 AR2 p of AR2 1 Age .05 S .05 .05 p g .05 Tenure .11 g .05 .06 p g .05 Education .11 g .05 .00 n.s Gender .11 g .05 .00 n.s 2 Past .15 g .05 .04 p g .05 Performance (PP) 3 Perceived .15 g .05 .00 n.s Reward Contingency (PRC) 4 PP x PRC .19 g .05 .04 p g .05 86 variance in pay satisfaction, compared to just 5% for age using standardized pay satisfaction. The main effects were essentially the same, as past performance explained an additional 5 percent of the variance (p g .05) in pay satisfaction, while the perceived reward contingency main effect accounted for none (ARZ=- .00, ppsp). However, unlike standardized pay satisfaction, the past performance X perceived reward contingency interaction accounted for significant additional variance (ARZ=- .04, p g .05) beyond the covariates and main effects for unstandardized pay satisfaction. The nature of this interaction is revealed in Figure 10, in which the relationship between past performance and pay satisfaction is plotted for values il.0 SQ units of unstandardized past performance. Consistent with previous research (Cherrington et. a1., 1971; Greene, 1973; and Jacobs & Soloman, 1977), the relationship between performance and unstandardized satisfaction is positive and stronger (p = .40, p g .05) under conditions of higher perceived reward contingency than under conditions of lower perceived reward contingency (L = .03, n s.). In practical terms, increasing perceived reward contingency one standard deviation (i.e., from Fisher g' = 1.14 to Fisher ;’ = 2.17; Pearson correlation equivalents are from p = .815 to p = .975) resulted in approximately a one standard deviation difference in unstandardized pay satisfaction between poor performers and high performers. Parallel analyses, the results of which are shown in Table 8, were conducted for unstandardized job satisfaction. However, unlike pay satisfaction, the results for unstandardized job satisfaction were nearly identical to those for standardized job satisfaction, meaning they were not significant. Pay Satisfaction 38 87 Figure 10: Regression of Unstandardized Pay Satisfaction on Past Performance by Perceived Reward Contingency Interaction - Low Perceived , Reward Contingency - r —‘ - High Perceived . Reward Contingency I 0 Past Performance 88 Table 8: Moderated Regression Analysis on Unstandardized Job Satisfaction Hierarchical Step Variable R2 p AR2 p of AR2 1 Age .00 pp .00 pp Tenure .00 pg .00 pp Education .00 pp .00 pp Gender .00 pp .00 pp 2 Past .00 pp .00 pp Performance (PP) 3 Perceived .00 pp .00 pg Reward Contingency (PRC) 4 PP x PRC .03 pp .03 pp 89 Evidence for study design. In summary, the evidence concerning the study design is positive. First, the primary design consideration was met since there were significant differences in objective reward contingency across all organizations. Second, even though the 4-1evel objective reward contingency design was associated with only a 2—level perceived reward contingency design (i.e., essentially a comparison between perceptions of complete contingency and strong partial contingency), objective reward contingency was strongly correlated (p = .56) with perceived reward contingency. Thus, the expectancy theory boundary conditions that workers must perceive clear performance reward contingencies, and, that objective reward contingencies should influence perceptions of reward contingencies, were met. Finally, consistent with previous research on reward contingency and satisfaction, perceived reward contingency did moderate the relationship between past performance and unstandardized pay satisfaction. While this moderated relationship did not hold for job satisfaction, the absence of that moderated relationship is understandable since pay satisfaction and job satisfaction are at best moderately related (see below), and because of evaluative consistency (Fisher, 1980), meaning that pay-related reward contingency should moderate the relationship between performance and the specific facet of pay satisfaction, but not an overall measure of general job satisfaction. Model Testing Hypotheses The statistics used to interpret discriminant and classification analysis are explained first. Then the results of the analysis, 90 beginning with hierarchical discriminant analysis which is used to test null hypotheses 5 and 6, proceeding to interpretation of discriminant functions, univariate analyses, and orthogonal contrasts, and ending with linear classification analyses, are reported. Interpreting discriminant analysis. In discriminant analysis, the significance and contribution of each discriminant function to group separation is indicated by the canonical correlation and Wilks lambda. The canonical correlation, RC, associated with each function represents the degree of relatedness between the groups and the discriminant function that is literally formed by correlating the discriminant variate, representing the linear combination of discriminating variables, with the groups' variate, which consists of the linear combination of the dummy coded group variables (Klecka, 1980, pp. 36-37). The larger the canonical R for each function, the more strongly the discriminant function is associated with group differences. Wilks lambda is an "inverse" multivariate measure of group differences. Values near zero indicate strong discrimination between groups, while values approaching 1 indicate progressively less discrimination (Klecka, 1980). Lambda parallels R2 in multiple regression because lambda subtracted from one represents the overall canonical R2, which is the proportion of variance in between-group differences accounted for by the discriminant functions (McLaughlin, 1980). Lambda yields both an overall chi-squared test, as well as providing a chi-squared test for each discriminant function. The rationale underlying lambda is to keep deriving discriminant functions until the residual discrimination is nonsignificant, in other words, 91 up to the point where additional discriminant functions fail to account for significant incremental separation between groups (Klecka, 1980). Rather than testing the lambda directly associated with the addition of a discriminant function, "we examine the residual discrimination in the system prior to deriving that function," (Klecka, 1980, p. 38). Thus, the reported lambdas are designated "Wilks lambda prior to removal of function" in the tables. Five statistics are used to test the classification analysis. The overall hit rate, which is the percentage of correctly classified cases across all groups, is tested by comparing it to the proportional chance criterion (Huberty, 1984). The proportional chance criterion indicates the percentage of correct hits that could be expected on the basis of chance alone (Huberty, 1984). Here, adjusted for differences in group sizes, that percentage is 33.28%. Huberty (1984, p. 166-167) provides a formula for a standardized normal statistic, Z. to test the significance of the overall hit rate compared to the proportional chance criterion. Last, it is crucial in functional turnover research to determine the classification accuracy of "separate-group" hit rates (Huberty, 1984). In this way, it becomes possible to specify which of the four groups (i.e., poor performing leavers, good performing leavers, poor performing stayers, or good performing stayers) a set of variables proves useful in classifying. Huberty (1984, p. 167, formula 9) also provides a formula for a standardized normal statistic, Z. to test the significance of separate-group hit rates. The first test for all discriminant analyses was the Box M test for homogeneity of variance-covariance matrices across groups (McLaughlin, 1980). When Box’s M was significant, quadratic 92 classification (classification based on separate group covariance matrices) was substituted for the default classification based on pooled covariance matrices. However, no adjustment is typically made to the discriminant analyses, even though the unequal covariance matrices will produce a conservative test by creating a bias in favor of the null hypothesis (McLaughlin, 1980). Null Hypothesis 5: The effects of objective reward contingency and perceived reward contingency on functional turnover will not be mediated by pay satisfaction and job satisfaction. Null Hypothesis 6: The effect of performance on satisfaction will not be moderated by perceived reward contingency. That is, there will be no significant pay satisfaction and job satisfaction differences across the four functional turnover groups. Before testing these hypotheses, recall that one consequence of the study design is that organization and objective reward contingency are confounded. One method of assessing the degree to which these variables are confounded is to dummy code organization, enter the three dummy coded organizational variables first in a discriminant analysis, and then enter objective reward contingency. If these variables are fully confounded, then the addition of objective reward contingency should not result in significant increases in variance or classification accuracy. As shown in Table 9, organization alone accounts for significant variance (29%; R? = 1 - Wilks Lambda) in functional turnover, while allowing classification of the four functional turnover groups (52%) at a rate significantly better than chance (33.28%). In comparison, objective reward contingency explained greater variance (34%) by itself than the organization dummy variables, while also producing 93 HNUHm 8“ cwmnfiwawswsfi vaHKmHm emmdwso awn nonwocsdma mmmmnnm om OHQmSHdewo: mum wmzde.06588:©m:n<. owmofl8gnsmsfi.>sm8dm8:m8mdmfi8mw 8:98omdmm numd ofiocw 38d 109 As mentioned above, the overall classification rate of 62.24% was significant when compared to the chance criterion. Based on a formula presented by Huberty (1984), this level of classification represented a 43% improvement over chance classification. In addition to assessing the overall level of classification, functional turnover research must also examine separate-group hit rates to determine which of the four functional turnover groups is accurately classified. In actuality, the significant level of overall classification demonstrated in Table 16 results only from accurate prediction of good and poor performing stayers. Neither good nor poor performing leavers were accurately classified. In other words, the large amounts of explained variance reported for the discriminant analysis results from the prediction of performance, from separating poor performing stayers from good performing stayers. Because of the upward bias in classification accuracy that occurs when "validation is based on the same cases used to derive the classification functions" (Klecka, 1980, p. 51), this classification analysis was double cross-validated using questionnaire nonresponders (n - 128, after attrition due to missing data) from each organization. However, since most of the discriminating variables were obtained by questionnaire, only a limited double cross-validation could be attempted. The data common to responders and nonresponders were overall performance and turnover, which permitted categorization of functional turnover groups, and total compensation and commissions, which served as the discriminating variables. A discriminant analysis of the original sample using only objective reward contingency (see Table 9) yielded one significant 110 discriminant function and an overall classification hit rate of 58.16% which was significant against the proportional chance criterion. The full classification matrix, shown in Table 17, again shows that the significant overall level of classification is attributable to prediction of good and poor performing stayers. A replication of that discriminant analysis using the sample of nonresponders yielded one significant discriminant function (Canonical R = .35, Wilks lambda - .88, chi-squared = 15.88, g: = 3, p g .0012) and an overall classification hit rate of 46.88%, which was significant against the proportional chance criterion (g = 2.89, p g .0019). That nonresponder classification matrix is shown in Table 18. Once more, the significant overall classification rate is attributable to prediction of good and poor performing stayers. The classification coefficients from the original sample were then used to classify the sample of nonresponders into functional turnover groups. The cross-validation classification matrix is shown in Table 19. There was some deterioration in predictive power because the cross-validation sample of nonresponders was predicted with 42.97% accuracy (g = 1.96, p 5 .0250), compared to 62.24% in the original sample. However, in contrast to previous analyses, only good performing stayers were classified at a rate better than chance. The linear classification functions from the sample of nonresponders were then used to double cross-validate cases from the original sample into functional turnover groups. The double cross- validation classification matrix is shown in Table 19. This time, there was much less deterioration in predictive power because the ll] 8.888888 88" 08888888888880: >388:m8nd5m8 chasm zmaUmHmU8w nmmmm 8 m u A 88 MUCH mMHMOHBHDQ Hmmmnmfi8mw 8sa8omdmm nsmn owoaw 38¢ Hmdm 8m m8od8M8omsn8958 08.086 396055888 ommmm 8 N u A 88 8.008. 38.808.58.30 8mmmnmfl8mw 859808188 $881“ 08.086 EH 3mm 8m m8058m80mbd8< 598an gm: 08558 E M .03 . 115 double cross-validated classification accuracy of 57.14% was significant when compared to the proportional chance criterion (; = 5.01, p 5 .00001), and was almost the same as the original classification accuracy of 58.16%. Again, the significant overall classification hit rate was due to classification of good and poor performing stayers. CHAPTER FIVE DISCUSSION The purpose of this field study was to investigate the relationship between reward contingency and functional turnover. The study was conducted across four companies, each of which rewarded its sales staff according to a different level of objective reward contingency, from mostly salary, to salary plus commission and bonuses, to straight commission. The results bearing on each of the substantive hypotheses, starting with hypothesis 6 and then hypothesis 5, are discussed below. (The results pertaining to the design hypotheses (1 -4) were discussed in Chapter 4). Stated in the affirmative, hypothesis 6 predicted that if perceived reward contingency moderated the relationship between performance and satisfaction, pay satisfaction and job satisfaction would be related to functional turnover (i e., lead to accurate discrimination between functional turnover groups). Yet, despite this moderated relationship for pay satisfaction, null hypothesis 6 could not be rejected because neither pay satisfaction nor job satisfaction contributed to significant separation of the four functional turnover groups. The only sizable difference in satisfaction, though not statistically significant, was that poor performing stayers, all of whom were paid on commission and had the lowest level of total compensation, reported lower pay satisfaction than the good performing 116 ll7 leavers and either group of stayers. In explaining why work attitudes (i.e. facets of job satisfaction, job involvement, organizational commitment, and motivation to turnover) that typically predicted turnover did not predict functional turnover, Hollenbeck and Williams (1986, p. 609) concluded, "The failure of job attitudes to predict turnover functionality can largely be attributed to the fact that, whereas related to one component of turnover functionality (i.e., turnover frequency), attitudes were unrelated to the second component (i e., performance)." So even though reward contingency was present and perceived in each organization, and even though perceived reward contingency moderated the relationship between performance and satisfaction, neither pay satisfaction nor job satisfaction was related to either component of functional turnover in the present study. However, objective reward contingency was related to both turnover and performance. One possible post hoc explanation for the absence of significant differences in satisfaction across functional turnover groups, especially pay satisfaction, is procedural justice (Thibaut & Walker, 1975; Greenberg, 1987). In other words, the presence of a commission system, regardless of the magnitude of differences in objective reward contingency across companies, may be sufficient to develop the belief that one's total compensation was justly earned, even if one's pay was low. This explanation was tested by conducting orthogonal contrasts between functional turnover groups on two items from the JDI pay satisfaction scale that were related to the issue of procedural justice. Some support was found for this hypothesis because there 118 were no differences across functional turnover groups on either item, "Less than I deserve" (E = 1.07, p g .37), and "Underpaid" (E = .44, p g .72). This suggests that poor performing leavers, good performing leavers, and good performing stayers, all of whom received most of their pay from commissions, felt no differently about the fairness of their pay than did poor performing stayers, who received most of their pay from salary rather than commissions. Stated in the affirmative, hypothesis 5 predicted that pay satisfaction and job satisfaction would mediate the effects of objective and perceived reward contingency. However, null hypothesis 5 also could not be rejected because objective reward contingency had a significant direct effect on functional turnover after controlling for pay satisfaction and job satisfaction. Even though pay satisfaction and job satisfaction did not account for differences in functional turnover, the full discriminant analysis still accounted for 56% of the variance in functional turnover groups, as well as an overall classification accuracy of 62.24%, which represented a 43% improvement over chance levels of prediction and was significant when judged against the proportional chance criterion. Examination of discriminant function structure coefficients and group centroids, in conjunction with follow-up univariate analyses and orthogonal contrasts, indicated that objective reward contingency accounted for most of that discriminatory power and classification accuracy. Indeed, objective reward contingency accounted for 34% of the variance in functional turnover groups and classification accuracy of 58.16%, which was significant when judged against the chance criterion. 119 Importantly, however, examination of separate-group hit rates indicated that the significant overall level of classification resulted from accurate classification of good and poor performing stayers. Good and poor performing leavers were not classified accurately, and were most often misclassified as good performing stayers. This pattern of classification results was replicated using a sample of nonresponders (n = 128) and then cross-validated and double cross—validated. While there was some shrinkage in classification accuracy in these additional analyses, overall classification was still better than chance in each case, and the pattern of separate-group hit rates was unchanged. Together, these analyses indicate that objective reward contingency does no more than separate good performers from poorer performers. In other words, objective reward contingency is strongly related to performance, but not to each of the four functional turnover groups. These results are at odds with meta-analytic data which suggest that reward contingency should be related to functional turnover. Williams and Livingstone (1990) found that reward contingency moderated the relationship between performance and voluntary turnover. When reward contingency was present, the sample-sized weighted average ; was -.30 with confidence intervals from -.27 to -.34. But when reward contingency was absent, the sample-sized weighted average g was -.18 with confidence intervals from -.15 to -.2l. As such, these meta-analytic data suggest that performance contingent pay is associated with a positive pattern of functional turnover where better performers are more likely to stay and poorer performers are more likely to leave. 120 In summary, the results of this study indicate a relationship between objective reward contingency and functional turnover, but that relationship occurs only because of accurate separation of good and poor performing stayers. Objective reward contingency did not lead to accurate classification of either good or poor performing leavers. And despite differences in objective reward contingency across companies, there were not significant pay satisfaction and job satisfaction differences across the four functional turnover groups. Finally, the effects of objective reward contingency were not mediated by differences in pay satisfaction and job satisfaction. Future Research and Theory There are several theoretical and methodological issues that should be considered when conducting functional turnover research in the future. External Eguity Perhaps the greatest theoretical weakness of the general model predicting positive functional turnover under conditions of high reward contingency is that it focuses on internal equity, how rewards are tied to performance within one company, without explicitly considering external equity, how much one could make by quitting and accepting a job with another company. Bergmann, Hills, and Priefert (1983) note that, "Externally, the organization must match the going rate' of the relevant labor market to remain competitive. Internally, employees must perceive equity both within and across jobs," (p. 17). External equity is especially important given that workers 121 usually improve their pay when they make an external job change. In reviewing a number of studies, Parnes (1954) argued that roughly 50- 60% of all quitters received better pay in their new jobs, while Rees and Schultz (1970) found that 57% of quitters took better paying new jobs. This effect, however, is even more pronounced for prearrangers, those who line up a new job prior to quitting their old one. Reynolds (1951) data indicated that 60% of prearrangers improved their wages compared to only 25% of "non-arrangers." In another study, Lansing and Mueller (1967) found that when quitting involved a geographic move, 72% of prearrangers increased their pay in contrast to 55% of those who did not prearrange a new job in their new location. That workers usually leave their present jobs for better paying jobs suggests that making rewards contingent on performance may be necessary, but not sufficient to produce positive functional turnover. Total compensation, even if it's performance based, must also be competitive in the external labor market. Several authors have suggested that external job opportunities influence the withdrawal process because they have a direct effect on job satisfaction (Hulin et. a1., 1985; Michaels & Spector, 1982). For example, if alternative better paying jobs were plentiful, the availability of those jobs might act to directly lower satisfaction with one's present job (Hulin et. a1., 1985). "The more abundant and desirable the alternatives, and the greater the expected utility of these other activities to a worker, the less the satisfaction experienced with the present job," (p. 242). A meta-analysis by Carsten and Spector (1987) offers some support for this View because the negative correlation between job satisfaction and turnover, as 122 well as the positive correlation between behavioral intentions and turnover, both become stronger when unemployment is down and weaker when unemployment is up. As they described it, "when there are few alternatives, dissatisfied employees who wish to quit cannot do so and there will be a small correlation observed between satisfaction and turnover. When there are many alternatives, dissatisfied employees who wish to quit can, and the observed relationship will become stronger," (p. 378). Although pay satisfaction and job satisfaction were unrelated to functional turnover in this study, better paying external job opportunities, according to this reasoning, could counteract the job satisfaction of better performers, even when rewards are linked to performance. In turn, lowered job satisfaction coupled with an offer for a better paying job might then lead to turnover. In contrast, if there were few alternative jobs, or if those jobs paid no better than other jobs, high reward contingency systems ought to lead to greater retention of better performers (Dreher, 1982; Wells & Muchinsky, 1985). The presently available evidence, however, does not support the notion that alternative employment opportunities are associated with negative functional turnover. Meta-analysis results (Williams & Livingstone, 1989) suggest that poorer performers, not better performers, are more likely to leave when more employment opportunities exist because there is a stronger negative relationship between performance and turnover when unemployment is low (for national, sample-size weighted average r = -.25 with confidence intervals from -.22 to - 28; for industry, -.22 with confidence 123 intervals from -.19 to -.26; for occupation, —.29 with confidence intervals from -.26 to -.32; for state, -.28 with confidence intervals from -.24 to -.33; and for city, -.27 with no confidence intervals because sampling error accounted for 100% of the variance across studies) and a weaker negative relationship when unemployment is high (for national, sample-size weighted average r = -.15 with confidence intervals from -.11 to - 19; for industry, -.18 with confidence intervals from -.11 to -.25; for occupation, -.14 with confidence intervals from -.09 to -.l9; for state, -.11 with confidence intervals from -.06 to -.l6; and for city, -.25 with confidence intervals from - .03 to -.27). Since reward contingency also leads to stronger negative relationships between performance and turnover, the use of reward contingency may be even more successful when alternative employment opportunities are frequent because poorer performers, who are less satisfied when rewards are contingent on performance, may become even more dissatisfied when alternative external jobs are widely available, too. Unfortunately, the effects of alternative employment opportunities were not estimated for this study. Therefore, we do not know the extent to which pay was perceived as competitive compared to alternative employment opportunities, the extent to which sales representatives actually had better or poorer alternative employment opportunities, or the extent to which other job alternatives actually affected pay satisfaction and job satisfaction. Undoubtedly, further research is needed to clarify the combined effects of satisfaction, reward contingency, and alternative employment opportunities on functional turnover. 124 Rewards Other ThagiBay Although the results of this study suggest that increases in reward contingency are associated with positive functional turnover, it is unlikely that the commission-based method of reward contingency used in this study can be applied to most jobs. Internal job opportunities. One readily available reward in many companies that can potentially counteract the influence of external job opportunities is the availability of internal job opportunities (March & Simon, 1958; Mobley, 1982). Preliminary research (Jackofsky and Peters, 1983; Todor, 1980) indicates that the processes for both organizational and job turnover are similar, and that internal mobility can greatly decrease employee turnover (Dalton & Todor, 1987). Moreover, the point of measuring and attempting to influence functional turnover is to retain better employees throughout the entire organization. Therefore, research that ignores internal movement, that excludes workers who have quit one job to take another within the same organization, misrepresents the effects of retention strategies. Just because a good worker takes another job in the same company doesn't indicate that the retention strategy was a failure. Rather, it indicates success. For example, several studies (Dreher, 1982; Stumpf and Dawley, 1981; and Wells and Muchinsky, 1985) already suggest that judicious use of promotions may help organizations improve functional turnover. In Dreher's study of managerial, professional, and technical employees at Exxon, leavers, who were significantly poorer performers, were promoted at a substantially slower rate than stayers. Stumpf and 125 Dawley (1981) also found that rate of promotion (i.e., indexed by the speed of promotion within the first 2 years; for example, from teller trainee, to junior teller, to intermediate teller, and then to senior teller) was negatively correlated with turnover (3 = -.33, from 1970- 1976; r = -.81 from 1977-1978) for bank tellers. And in a study of entry level credit managers, Wells and Muchinsky (1985) reported that promoted employees performed significantly better on all 12 performance dimensions than did those who left voluntarily. Expected Utility. The uniformity of results across these promotion studies, however, does not imply that all an organization must do is make promotion contingent on performance. Rather, Wells and Muchinsky (1985) speculate that there is also an important feedback component at work. Based on Ashford and Cummings (1983) who state "it is clear that individuals often use such feedback (performance appraisal information) in making turnover decisions" (1983, p. 375), Wells and Muchinsky argue that early performance appraisal information sets up a self-fulfilling prophecy that leads employees to "infer" their potential for future success with a company which, in turn, affects quit/stay decisions. For example, the credit managers in Wells and Muchinsky's study received performance appraisal information relatively early, after 2, 3, and 4 months on the job. In Dreher's (1982) study, early career variables, such as initial performance appraisal, initial job level, and initial rating of potential (which estimated the probable, final job level that the individual would achieve with the organization), were significantly better for stayers who were promoted more often than leavers. And in the Stumpf and Dawley study (1981), the authors noted: 126 "After 3 to 4 months, average and above average tellers were promoted to junior tellers, and on to intermediate tellers after 9 to 12 months service. The promotion to senior teller one or more years later required one to be able to perform all aspects of the job with little or no supervision. During the initial period of employment, promotional increases provide direct feedback on teller assimilation of training. Early promotion increases also serve to notify tellers of management’s view of the future potential" (1981, p. 152). Together, these studies suggest that the absence or presence of early rewards and promotions may shape expectations concerning future potential with the company, independent of job satisfaction. In fact, Mobley (1982) and his colleagues (1979) expressly separate the two in their model of employee turnover, viewing satisfaction as an affective reaction to one's present job, and the "expected utility" of one's present job as the expectancy "that the job will lead to future attainment of various positively and negatively valued outcomes" (1979, p. 518) within the same company. "It is important to recognize that just as the dissatisfied employee may not quit, given positive expectations about future roles in the organization, the currently satisfied employee who has negative expectations about the future in the organization may quit. For example, expected negative changes in the job, the lack of perceived desirable promotional opportunities, and expected negative changes in policy, practices, or conditions may lead currently satisfied employees to seek external jobs," (Mobley, 1982, pp. 128-129). Job Design. Dunham (1977), Schneider, Reichers, and Mitchell (1982), and Campion (1989) have investigated the relationship between job design and ability because changes in the design of jobs may affect the selection, placement, training, and compensation of workers. One of their primary considerations has been that "redesigned jobs may not be compatible with the abilities of job incumbents," (Schneider et. a1., 1982, p. 568). This concern arises 127 because increases in job complexity are associated with increases in the abilities required to perform redesigned jobs. For example, Dunham (1977) found positive relationships (from .21 to .49) between measures of job characteristics and nine General Aptitude Test Battery (GATB) scores derived from the Position Analysis Questionnaire (McCormick, Jeanneret & Meacham, 1972). Schneider et. a1. (1982) directly coded GATB scores for 140 jobs and found them to be positively correlated with job characteristics (i.e., identity, variety, required interdependence, predictability, autonomy, and feedback). Campion (1989) estimated job ability requirements from the Dictionary of Occupational Titles as well as the GATB scores for 200 jobs across two samples. He then used factor analysis to reduce the 31 different ability measures to a smaller and more interpretable number of common factors. The first factor from that analysis, substantive complexity (which reflected intelligence, verbal, numerical, spatial, form, clerical, data, people, and talk ability scales), correlated .55 with the motivational components of jobs (i.e., autonomy, responsibility, extrinsic feedback, task variety, task identity, task significance, learning, and participation) in his first sample and .46 in the second. While this research forewarns that job redesign may unintentionally create a mismatch between job requirements and worker abilities, it also seems to suggest that workers with greater ability, who on average will be better performers, will respond positively to job enrichment and enlargement. For example, Schneider et. al. (1982) found that two task characteristics, variety and autonomy (from .46 to .52), were as strongly related to work satisfaction as were the 128 intelligence, verbal, and numerical scales of the GATB (from .39 to .51). Therefore, it is predicted that better performing employees will value enriched and enlarged jobs. According to Hackman and Oldham (1980): "For jobs high in motivating potential, then, people who have sufficient knowledge and skill to perform well will experience substantially positive feelings as a result of their work activities. But people who are not competent enough to perform well will experience a good deal of unhappiness and frustration at work, precisely because the job ’counts' for them and they do poorly at it," (p. 84). And if better performers experience positive feelings as a result of enriched and enlarged jobs, perhaps they may be more likely to stay. Performance and Turnover Despite knowing that performance and turnover are inversely related, that low unemployment and reward contingency moderate this relationship such that poor performers are more likely to leave and good performers are more likely to stay when external jobs are plentiful and when rewards are contingent on performance, and, that the relationship between performance and turnover is also u-shaped such that both good and poor performers, relative to average performers, are more likely to quit (Williams & Livingstone, 1989), there is little else that we know about the relationship between performance and turnover. For example, we don't know if good and bad performers frame turnover decisions differently. When poor performers quit, is it because they're withdrawing from a negative situation? Or, conversely, when better performers, is it because they are attracted 129 to a better job rather withdrawing from their present job? In other words, we don't even know if good and bad performers leave for the same or different reasons. Similarly, despite predictions of a positive relationship, "that the greater the job performance, the greater number of actual or perceived alternative job offers an individual receives," Jackofsky (1984, p. 77), we don't know if high performers actually have or perceive more external employment alternatives, and if they do, how that influences turnover decisions. Jackofsky and Peters (1980), using ability measured by selection tests (e.g., cognitive, clerical, and mathematical ability) as a surrogate for performance, found that even though employees with more ability had stronger expectations of finding alternative employment (; = .45, p < .05), they were not any more likely to quit than low ability employees. Ekpo-Ufot (1976) found that the higher one’s self-perceptions of ability, the more likely one was to stay on the job (; = -.34, p g .05), just the opposite of Jackofsky's prediction. Likewise, we know little about the relationship between actual employment alternatives and performance. Even Jackofsky (1984), who has made the argument for a positive relationship between performance and actual employment alternatives, admits that the evidence is anecdotal: "Support for this link can be found, not in empirical literature, but from statements made by personnel administrators," (p. 77). And, although some preliminary hypotheses have been made here with respect to job design, we also don't know if better performers value different rewards than do poorer performers. Nor do we know how strong reward contingency must be before positive functional turnover 130 results. Efforts to successfully influence functional turnover are likely to be unsuccessful unless we address these basic questions. Controllability of Turnover The impact that an organization can have on functional turnover through any variable or intervention, not just reward contingency, is limited by the portion of turnover that can be controlled by organizations. Dalton et. al. (1981, 1982) and Abelson (1987) argue that much voluntary turnover is unavoidable due to reasons such as returning to school for continued education, transfer of a spouse, death in the family, retirement, health, and so on. Empirical research suggests that a substantial percentage of turnover may occur for these reasons and, therefore, cannot be directly controlled by organizations. For example, Dalton, et. a1., (1981) indicated that for bank tellers fully 46% of voluntary turnover was unavoidable and could not be controlled. Abelson (1987) found that 35% of nursing personnel turnover in nursing homes was also unavoidable. The practical implication is that interventions designed to produce positive functional turnover can only be expected to influence avoidable separations, individuals who leave for better pay, working .conditions, leadership, etc. In Abelson’s study, 65% of voluntary turnover occurred for such reasons, while in Dalton et. al.'s study only 54% of voluntary turnover was controllable. The scientific implication is that judgments of the success or failure of organizational programs designed to influence the pattern of functional turnover may be invalid to the extent that voluntary 131 turnover is not separated into avoidable and unavoidable quits. Thus, controllability or avoidability represents another important refinement in the measurement of turnover. Failure to make this refinement could lead to a loss of prediction, understanding, and parsimony when testing turnover models. In the present study, the extent of unavoidable turnover and its possible effect on the results if unavoidable voluntary quits were removed from the analysis cannot be discerned. Yet, given the extent of unavoidable turnover in the Dalton et. a1. (1981) and Abelson (1987) studies, future functional turnover research should attempt to distinguish between avoidable and unavoidable quits. Field Experiments Finally, perhaps the most important methodological change that must be made in measuring and determining the antecedents of functional turnover is a move away from predictive designs which predominate in turnover research toward the use of basic field experiments. "Although thousands of studies have been done, only a few field experiments have addressed the crucial problem that is of most interest to managers--how to reduce turnover among those employees an organization wishes to retain," (McEvoy and Cascio, 1985, p. 351). While researchers may encounter difficulties in obtaining research sights when conducting field experiments, and while it may be difficult to randomly assign subjects to treatments (treatments will more likely have to be assigned to groups of subjects to accommodate host organizations), field experiments can help control a number of threats to internal validity, such as history, maturation, selection, 132 mortality, interactions of selection-maturation and selection-history, all of which may provide alternative explanations when comparing results across studies or, as in this study, when trying to make sense of functional turnover results which have been compiled across different organizations. REFERENCES REFERENCES Abelson, M.A. (1987). Examination of avoidable and unavoidable turnover. Journal pf Applied Psychology 72 382-386. ’ _’ Abelson, M.A., & Baysinger, B.D. (1984). Optimal and dysfunctional turnover: Toward an organizational level model. Academy pf Management Review, 2, 331-341. Armknecht, P.A., & Early, J.F. (1972). Quits in manufacturing: A study of their causes. Monthly Labor Review, 95 31-37. —’ Ashford, S.J., & Cummings, L.L. (1983). Feedback as an individual resource: Personal strategies of creating information. Bagozzi, R.P. (1978). Salesforce performance and satisfaction as a function of individual difference, interpersonal, and situational factors. Journal pf Marketing Research, 15, 517- 531. Bagozzi, R.P. (1980). Performance and satisfaction in an industrial sales force: An examination of their antecedents and their simultaneity. Journal pf Marketing, 44, 65-77. Baird, L.S., & Hamner, W.C. (1979). Individual versus system rewards: Who's dissatisfied, why, and what is their likely response? Academy pf Management Journal, 22,783-792. Baxter,B., Taaffe, A.A., & Hughes, J.F. (1955). Unpublished study, cited in Brayfield & Crockett, 1955. Bergmann, T.J., Hills, F.S., & Priefert, L. (1983). Pay compression: Causes, results and possible solutions. Compensation Review, 15, 17-26. Bhagat, R.S. (1982). Conditions under which stronger job performance- job satisfaction relationships may be observed: A closer look at two situational contingencies. Academy pf Management Journal, 25, 772-789. Boudreau, J.W. (1981). A conceptual model of employee movement utility. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Purdue University. Boudreau, J.W. (1983). Effects of employee flows on utility analysis of human resource productivity improvement programs. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 68, 396-406. 133 134 Boudreau, J.W., & Berger, C.J. (1985). Decision-theoretic utility analysis applied to employee separations and acquisitions [Monograph]. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 10, 581—612. Brayfield, A.H., & Crockett, W.H. (1955). Employee attitudes and employee performance. Psychological Bulletin 52 396-324. Brody, M. (1945). The relationship between efficiency and job satisfaction. Unpublished M.A. thesis, New York University. Bureau of National Affairs. (1982). Collective bargaining negotiations and contracts. Daily Labor Report, 206A, 8. Burton, J.F., & Parker, J.E. (1969). Interindustry variation in voluntary labor mobility. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 22, 199-216. Campion, M.A. (1989). Ability requirement implications of job design: An interdisciplinary perspective. Personnel Psychology, 42, 1-24. Carsten, J.M., & Spector, P.E. (1987). Unemployment, job satisfaction, and employee turnover: A meta-analytic test of the Muchinsky model. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 1;, 374-381. Cascio, W.F. (1982). Costing human resources: The financial impact pf behavior ip organizations. Boston: Kent. Cherrington, D.J., Reitz, H.J., & Scott, W.E., Jr.. (1971). Effects of contingent and noncontingent reward on the relationship between satisfaction and task performance. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 52, 531-536. Cohen, J., & Cohen, P. (1983). Applied multiple regression/correlation f9; phg behavioral sciences, (2nd ed.). Hillsdale, N.J.: Erlbaum. Cook, T.D., & Campbell, D.T. (1979). Quasi-experimentation: Design and analysis issues for field settings. Chicago: Rand McNally. Cronbach, L.J., & Gleser, G.C. (1965). Psychological tests and personnel decisions. Urbana, Ill.: University of Illinois Press. Dachler, H.P., & Mobley, W.H. (1973). Construct validation of an instrumentality-expectancy-task-goal model of work motivation: Some theoretical boundary conditions [Monograph]. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 58, 397-418. Dalton, D.R., Krackhardt, D.M., & Porter, L.W. (1981). Functional turnover: An empirical assessment. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 66, 716-721. 135 Dalton, D.R., Todor, W.D. (1979). Turnover turned over: An expanded and positive perspective. Academy pf Management Review, 4, 225- 235. Dalton, D.R., Todor, W.D. (1987). The attenuating effects of internal mobility on employee turnover: Multiple field assessments: Journal pf Management, 13, 705-711. Dalton, D.R., Todor, W.D., & Krackhardt, D.M. (1982). Turnover overstated: The functional taxonomy. Academy pf Management Review, 1, 117-123. Dansereau, F., Jr., Cashman, J., & Graen, G. (1973). Instrumentality theory and equity theory as complementary approaches in predicting the relationship of leadership and turnover among managers. Organizational Behavior app Human Performance, 10, 184-200. Dreher, G.F. (1977). Nonrespondent characteristics and respondent accuracy in salary research. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 62, 773-776. Dreher, G.F. (1982). The role of performance in the turnover process. Academy pf Management Journal, 25, 137-147. Dreher, G.F., Ash, R.A., Hancock, P. (1988). The role of the traditional research design in underestimating the validity of the employment interview. Personnel Psychology, 41, 315-327. Dunham, R.B. (1977). Relationship of perceived job design characteristics to job ability requirements and job values. Journal pf Applied Psychology, ,62, 760-763. Dunham, R.B., & Herman, J.B. (1975). Development of a female Faces Scale for measuring job satisfaction. Journal pf Applied Psychology, pp, 629-631. Dyer, L., & Theriault, R. (1976). The determinants of pay satisfaction. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 61, 596-604. Eagly, R.V. (1965). Market power as an intervening mechanism in Phillips Curve analysis. Economics, 32, 48-64. Ekpo-Ufot, A. (1976). Self-perceived abilities-—relevant in the task (SPART): A potential predictor of labor turnover in an industrial setting. Personnel Psychology, 22, 405-416. Fisher, C.D. (1980). On the dubious wisdom of expecting job satisfaction to correlate with performance. Academy pf Management Review, 5, 607-612. Flamholtz, E. (1974). Human resources accounting. Encino, CA: Dickenson Publishing. 136 Fleishman, E.A., & Harris, E.F. (1962). Patterns of leadership behavior related to employee grievances and turnover. Personnel Psychology, 25, 43-56. Ghiselli, E.E., Campbell, J.P., Zedeck, S. (1981). Measurement theory for the behavioral sciences. San Francisco: W.H. Freeman and Company. Glass, G.V., & Stanley, J.C. (1970). Statistical methods 53 education and psychology. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall. Graen, G.B. (1969). Instrumentality theory of work motivation: Some experimental results and suggested modifications [Monograph]. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 55. Graen, G.B., Dansereau, F., & Minami, T. (1972). Dysfunctional leadership styles. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 1, 216-236. Greenberg, J. (1987). Reactions to procedural injustice in payment distributions: Do the means justify the ends? Journal pf Applied Psychology, 12, 55-61. Greene, C. N. (1973). Causal connections among managers' merit pay, job satisfaction, and performance. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 52, 95-100. Greenhaus, J.H., & Badin, I.J. (1974). Self-esteem, performance, and satisfaction: Some tests of a theory. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 52, 722-726. Gustafson, H.W. (1980). Force-loss cost analysis. New York: American Telephone and Telegraph Co. Hackman, J.R., & Oldham, G.R. (1980). Work redesign. Reading, Mass: Addison-Wesley. Hamner, W.C., & Harnett, D.L. (1974). Coal setting, performance, and satisfaction in an interdependent task. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 12, 217-230. Heneman, H.G. (1973). Impact of performance on managerial pay levels and pay changes. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 52, 128-130. Herzberg, F., Mausner, B., Peterson, R.O., & Capwell, R.F. (1957). Job attitudes: Review of research and opinions. Pittsburgh, PA.: Pittsburgh Psychological Services. Hinrichs, J.R. (1969). Correlates of employee evaluations of pay increases. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 55, 481-489. Hollenbeck, J.R., & Williams, G.R. (1986). Turnover functionality versus turnover frequency: A note on work attitudes and organizational effectiveness. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 1;, 606-611. 137 Hoppock, R. (1935). Job Satisfaction. Harper and Brothers, New York. Reprint Edition by Arno Press, New York, 1977. Huberty, C.J. (1984). Issues in the use and interpretation of discriminant analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 25, 156-171. Huberty, C.J., & Morris, J.D. (1989). Multivariate analysis versus multiple univariate analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 105, 302- 308. Hulin, C.L. (1968). Effects of changes in job-satisfaction levels on employee turnover. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 52, 122-126. Hulin, C.L., Roznowski, M., & Hachiya, D. (1985). Alternative opportunities and withdrawal decisions: Empirical and theoretical discrepancies and an integration. Psychological Bulletin, 21, 233-250. Iaffaldano, M.T., & Muchinsky, P.M. (1985). Job satisfaction and job performance: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 21, 251- 273. Ilgen, D.R., Nebeker, D.M., Pritchard, R.D. (1981). Expectancy theory measures: An empirical comparison in an experimental simulation. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 22, 189-223. Ilgen, D.R., Pritchard, R.D., Dugoni, B.L., & Nebeker, D.M. (1980). models fog th; predictions pf perfgrmance lg ap experimental work simulation, (Technical Report). San Diego: Navy Personnel Research and Development Center. Jackofsky, E.F. (1984). Turnover and job performance: An integrated process model. Academy pf Management Review, 2, 74-83. Jackofsky, E.F., & Peters, L.H. (1980). Task-relevant ability and turnover: Test of a model. Southwest Academy 95 Management Proceedings, 161-165. Jackofsky, E.F., & Peters, L.H. (1983). Job turnover versus company turnover: Reassessment of the March and Simon participation hypothesis. Journal pf Applied Psychology 68 490-495. ’ ..._.7 Jacobs, R., & Solomon, T. (1977). Strategies for enhancing the prediction of job performance from job satisfaction. Journal 95 Applied Psychology, 52, 417-421. James, L.R., & Brett, J.M. (1984). Mediators, moderators, and tests for mediation. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 52, 307-321. Jenning, K., & Wolters, R. (1976). Discharge cases reconsidered. Arbitration Journal 31 164-180. 138 Jeswald, T.A., (1974). The cost of absenteeism and turnover in a large organization. In W.C. Hamner & F.L. Schmidt (Eds.), Contemporary problems 1p personnel. Chicago: St. Clair Press. . Johnson, S.M., Smith, P.C., Tucker, S.M. (1982). Response format of the Job Descriptive Index: Assessment of reliability and validity by the multitrait-multimethod matrix. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 21, 500-505. Keller, R.T. (1984). The role of performance and absenteeism in the prediction of turnover. Academy 2: Management Journal, 21, 176- 183. Kesselman, G.A., Wood, M.T., & Hagen, E.L. (1974). Relationships between performance and satisfaction under contingent and noncontingent reward systems. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 52, 374-376. Kirchner, W.K. (1965). Relationships between general and specific attitudes toward work and objective job performance for outdoor advertising salesmen. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 22, 455- 457. Klecka, W.R. (1980). Discriminant analysis. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Kopelman, R.E. (1976). Organizational control system responsiveness, expectancy theory constructs, and work motivation: Some interrelations and causal connections. Personnel Psychology, 22, 205-220. Kopelman, R.E., & P.H. Thompson. (1976). Boundary conditions for expectancy theory predictions of work motivation and job performance. Academy pf Management Journal 19 237-258. ’ —’ l | Kulik, J.A., Kulik, C.-L.C., & Cohen, P.A. (1979). A meta-analysis of i outcome studies of Keller’s personalized system of instruction. American Psychologist, 22, 307-318. 1 Kunin, T. (1955). The construction of a new type of attitude measure. Personnel Psychology, 2, 65-78. Lansing, J.B., & Mueller, E. (1967). The geographic mobility pi labor. Ann Arbor, Mi.: University of Michigan Press. Lawler, E.E. (1966). Manager’s attitudes toward how their pay is and should be determined. Journal pf Applied Psychology, 52, 273- 279. Lawler, E.E., & Porter, L.T. (1967). The effect of performance on job satisfaction. Industrial Relations, 1, 20-28. Locke, E.A. (1965). The relationship of task success to task liking and satisfaction. Journal 92 Applied Psychology, 22, 379-385. 139 MacKinney, A.C., & Wolins, L. (1959). Validity information exchange. Personnel Psychology, 12, 482-483. Macy, B.A., & Mirvis, P.H. (1983). Assessing rates and costs of individual work behaviors. In S.E. Seashore, E.E. Lawler, P.H. Mirvis, & C. Cammann (Eds.), Assessing organizational change. New York: Wiley. March, J.C., & Simon, H.A. (1958). Organizations. New York: Wiley. Matteson, M.T., Ivancevich, J.M., & Smith, S.V. (1984). Relation of type A behavior to performance and satisfaction among sales personnel. Journal 92 Vocational Behavior, 25, 203-214. McCormick, E.J., Jeanneret, P.R., & Mecham, R.C. (1972). A study of job characteristics and job dimensions as based on the Position Analysis Questionnaire (PAQ). Journal 9: Applied Psychology, 52, 347-368. McEvoy, G.M., & Cascio, W.F. (1985). Strategies for reducing employee turnover: A meta-analysis. Journal 22 Applied Psychology, 12, 342-363. McEvoy, G.M., & Cascio, W.F. (1987). Do good or poor performers leave? A meta-analysis of the relationship between performance and turnover. Academy pi Management Journal, 22, 744-762. McIntyre, R.M. (1990). Spurious estimation of validity coefficients in composite samples: Some methodological considerations. Journal 2: Applied Psychology, 15, 91-94. McLaughlin, M.L. (1980). Discriminant analysis in communication research. In P.R. Monge & J.N. Cappella (Eds.), Multivariate Techniques 1p Human Communication Research. New York, NY: Academic Press. McNichols, C.W., Stahl, M.J., & Manley, T.R. (1978). A validation of Hoppock's job satisfaction measure. Academy pf Management Journal, 21, 737-742. Michaels, C.E., & Spector, P.E. (1982). Causes of employee turnover: A test of the Mobley, Griffeth, Hand, and Meglino model. Journal 91 Applied Psychology, 21, 53-59. Miner, J.B. (1980). Theories pf organizational behavior. Hinsdale, ILL.: The Dryden Press. Mirvis, P.H., & Lawler, E.E. (1977). Measuring the financial impact of employee attitudes. Journal 91 Applied Psychology, 22, 1-8. Mitchell, T.R. (1974). Expectancy models of job satisfaction, occupational preference and effort: A theoretical, methodological, and empirical appraisal. Psychological Bulletin, 21, 1053-1077. 140 Mobley, W.H. (1982). Employee turnover: Causes conseguences, and control. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley. Mobley, W.H., Griffeth, R.W., Hand, H.H., Meglino, B.M. (1979). Review and conceptual analysis of the employee turnover process. ’ -’ Psychological Bulletin 86 493-522. Motowidlo, S.J. (1982). Relationship between self-rated performance and pay satisfaction among sales representatives. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 21, 209-213. Mowday, R.T., Porter, L.T., & Steers, R.M. (1982). Employee- organization linkages: The psychology pi commitment, absenteeism and turnover. New York: Academic Press. Muchinsky, P.M., & Tuttle, M.L. (1979). Employee turnover: An empirical and methodological assessment. Journal pi Vocational Behavior, 12, 43-77. Orpen, C. (1974). The effect of reward contingencies on the job satisfaction-task performance relationship: An industrial experiment. Psychology, 11, 9-14. Parnes, H.S. (1954). Research pp labor mobility. New York: Social Science Research Council. Podsakoff, P.M., & Williams, L.J. (1986). The relationship between job performance and job satisfaction. In E.A. Locke (Ed.), Generalizing from laboratory ip field settings (pp. 205-253). Lexington, Mass: Lexington Books. Porter, L.W., & Lawler, E.E. (1968). Managerial attitudes and performance. Homewood, Ill: Irwin. Porter, L.W., & Steers, R.M. (1973). Organizational, work, and personal factors in employee turnover and absenteeism. Psychological Bulletin, 22, 151-176. Price, J.L. (1977). The study pi turnover. Ames, Iowa: Iowa State University Press. Pritchard, R.D. (1973). Effects of varying performance-pay instrumentalities on the relationship between performance and satisfaction.: A test of the Lawler and Porter model. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 52, 122-125. Rees, A., & Shultz, G.P. (1970). Workers and wages ip ap urban labor market. Chicago, 111.: University of Chicago Press. Reynolds, L.G. (1951). The structure pi labor markets. New York: Harper. Robinson, W.S. (1950). Ecological correlations and the behavior of individuals. American Sociological Review 15 351-357. I _ ’ 141 Saunders, D.R. (1956). Moderator variables in prediction. Educational and Psychological Measurement, 12, 209-222. Schmidt, F.L., & Hoffman, B. (1973). Empirical comparison of three methods of assessing utility of a selection device. Journal pi Industrial and Organizational Psychology, 13-22. Schmidt, F.L., Hunter, J.E., McKenzie, R.C., & Muldrow, T.W. (1979). Impact of valid selection procedures on work-force productivity. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 22, 609-626. Schmidt, F.L., & Hunter, J.E., & Raju, N.S. (1988). Validity generalization and situational specificity: A second look at the 75% rule and Fisher's z transformation. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 12, 665-672. Schneider, B., & Olson, L.K. (1970). Effort as a correlate of organizational reward system and individual values. Personnel Psychology, 22, 313-326. Schneider, B., Reichers, A.E., & Mitchell, T.M. (1982). A note on some relationships between the aptitude requirements and reward attributes of tasks. Academy pi Management Journal, 25, 567- 564. Schwab, D.P. (1973). Impact of alternative compensation systems on pay valence and instrumentality perceptions. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 52, 308-312. Schwab, D.P., & Cummings, L.L. (1970). Theories of performance and satisfaction: A review. Industrial Relations, 2, 408-430. Smith, H.L., & Watkins, L.E. (1978). Managing manpower turnover costs. The Personnel Administrator, 22, 46-50. Smith, P.C., Budzeika, K.A., Edwards, N.A., Johnson, S.M., & Bearse, L.H. (1986). Guidelines for clean data: Detection of common mistakes. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 11, 457-460. Smith, P.C., Kendall, L., & Hulin, C.L. (1969). The measurement pi satisfaction 1p work and retirement. Chicago: Rand McNally. Sockloff, A.L. (1975). Behavior of the product-moment correlation coefficient when two heterogeneous subgroups are pooled. Educational and Psychological Measurement, 25, 267-276. Steel, R.P., & Ovalle, N.K. (1984). A review and meta-analysis of research on the relationship between behavioral intentions and employee turnover. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 22, 673-686. Steers, R.M., Mowday, R.T. (1981). Employee turnover and post- decision accommodation processes. In L.L. Cummings & B.M. Staw (Eds.), Research 1p Organizational Behavior (Vol. 3). Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press. 142 Stogdill, R.M., & Coons, A.E. (1957). Leader behavior' Its description and measurement. Columbus, Ohio: Bureau of Business Research. Stone, E.F., & Hollenbeck, J.R. (1984). Some issues associated with the use of moderated regression. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 22, 195-213. Stumpf, S.A., & Dawley, P.K. (1981). Predicting voluntary and involuntary turnover using absenteeism and performance indices. Academy pi Management Journal, 22, 148-163. Thibaut, J., & Walker, L. (1975). Procedural justice: A psychological analysis. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum. Todor, W.D. (1980). A movement paradox: Turnovail Transfer?. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Academy of Management. Van der Merwe, R., & Miller, S. (1971). The measurement of labor turnover: A critical appraisal and a suggested new approach. Human Relations, 22, 233-253. Vroom, V.H. (1964). Work and motivation. New York: Wiley. Wanous, J.P., Stumpf, S.A. & Bedrosian, H. (1979). Job survival of new employees. Personnel Psychology, 22, 651-662. Wells, D.L., & Muchinsky, P.M. (1985). Performance antecedents of voluntary and involuntary turnover. Journal pi Applied Psychology, 12, 329-336. Williams, G.R., & Livingstone, L.P. (1989). A second look at the relationship between performance and voluntary turnover. Manuscript submitted for review. Zedeck, S. (1971). Problems with the use of moderator variables. Psychological Bulletin 76 295-310. ’ _’ APPENDIX APPENDIX Study Questionnaire Michigan State Studies pp Attitudes and Organizational Memberahip This questionnaire is part of an ongoing program of scientific research at Michigan State University's Graduate School of Business. Specifically, this research is concerned with attitudes and how they affect 1) individual job performance, and 2) employee turnover. In order to comply with the ethical standards established by the American Psychological Association and the Academy of Management, it is essential that all participants in this research be made aware of: 1) what is reguired of each participant, 2) the rights of each participant, and 3) the responsibilities of each participant. 1) Participant Requirementa * if you choose to participate in this research, we will need no more than 30 minutes of your time. In addition to the questionnaire, we also need to know your performance with the company. Without access to these records, we will be unable to determine how your attitudes toward your job are related to your job performance and organizational membership. Complete confidentiality for all participants is guaranteed. See below for more. 2) Participant Rights * Participation in this research is voluntary. further, should you choose to participate, you may end your participation at any time. Each participant is guaranteed complete confidentiality. No one in your organization will have access to or ever see your individual questionnaire responses. Thus, you can be assured that your participation in this research will in no way influence your job with your company. 143 144 Your confidentiality will be protected when you seal the questionnaire in the pre-addressed, pre-stamped envelope and mail it directly to Chuck Williams at the Graduate School of Business, Michigan State University. 3) Participant Responsibilities * Please provide information that is honest, accurate and complete. By completing the entire questionnaire as honestly as possible, you can help increase our understanding of the relationships between employee attitudes, performance and turnover. Print and sign your name to the Informed Consent Declaration shown below. Also print your name on the first page of the questionnaire. Your name must be on the questionnaire in order to link your attitudes as measured by the questionnaire to your performance and organizational membership. Remember, your confidentiality is guaranteed. ********************************************************************** Informed Consent Declaration I certify that I have read and understand the requirements, rights and responsibilities incurred by both the participants and the researcher in this study. I voluntarily agree to participate in this research and give the researcher permission to collect questionnaire data from me and review my sales performance records. (PRINT YOUR NAME) (SIGN YOUR NAME) ********************************************************************** THANK YOU FOR PARTICIPATING IN THIS RESEARCH STUDY Charles R. Williams 232 Eppley Center Department of Management Michigan State University East Lansing, MI 48824 (517) 353-5415 PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE 145 SECTION 1 ----------------------- INSTRUCTIONS-----------------------—-----—-—--- Please provide general information about yourself in the following spaces. Fill in the blanks or choose ( J ) the option which describes you. Please respond to a11 categories. Name: Sex: Male Female City/State (Territory) Where you Work or Where you are Based: City State How long have you worked for this company? years months What is your job title? Associate Sales Representative Showroom Representative Sales Representative Senior Sales Representative other How long have you been doing this job for this company? years months How long have you been in sales for this company? years months How much education have you had? Place a check mark in the appropriate space. Some High-School Graduated High-School Some College Graduated College Some Graduate School Master's Degree M.D., Ph.D., or some other professional degree PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE AND SECTION 146 SECTION 2 ----------------------- INSTRUCTIONS----------------------------------- In the following sections, place a "Y" (for Yes) next to the item if it accurately describes your job. Place an "N" (for No) next to the item if it does not accurately describe your job. If you cannot decide whether the item accurately describes your job or not, place a "?" (for Uncertain) beside the item. PAY Income adequate for Insecure normal expenses Satisfactory profit Less than I deserve sharing Barely live on Highly paid income Income provides Underpaid luxuries Bad PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE AND SECTION 147 SECTION 3 ----------------------- INSTRUCTIONS------—---------------------------- For each of the 4 items below, check the one item which best represents your beliefs and feelings. 1) Choose the one of the following statements which best tells how well you like your job. Place a check mark next to that statement. I hate it. I dislike it. I don't like it. ' I am indifferent to it. I like it. I am enthusiastic about it. I love it. 2) Check one of the following to show how much of the time your feel satisfied with your job. All of the time Most of the time. A good deal of the time. About half of the time. Occasionally. Seldom. Never. PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE 3) 4) 148 Check the one of the following which best tells how you feel about changing your job. I would quit this job at once if I could get anything else to do. I would take almost any other job in which I could earn as much as I am earning now. I would like to change both my job and my occupation. I would like to exchange my present job for another job in the same kind of work. I am not eager to change my job but I would do so if I could get a better job. I cannot think of any jobs for which I would exchange mine. I would not exchange my job for any other. Check one of the following to show how much you think you compare with other people: No one likes his job better than I like mine. I like my job much better than most people like theirs. I like my job better than most people like theirs. I like my job about as well as most people like theirs. I dislike my job more than most people dislike theirs. I dislike my job much more than most people dislike theirs. No one dislikes his job more than I dislike mine. PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE 149 SECTION 4 ----------------------- INSTRUCTIONS----------------------------------- The following questions are concerned with how long it takes a new sales representative in your company to learn how to do his/her sales job well. Circle the time on the scale below which you believe indicates how long it takes a new sales representative in your company to learn how to do that part of their sales job. for example, if it takes 1 year and 3 months, you would circle ..... 4 1 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS 0--/--/--/--l--/--/--/--2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--l+ 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS How long does it take a new sales representative in your company to... 1) learn the design and specifications of the company products? A 1 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS 1 -2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--4 0--/--/--/-- --/--/-- 6 9 3 6 3 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 S MONTHS MONTH MONTHS MONTHS 2) learn the applications and functions of company products? 4 1 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS 1 -2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--4 0--/--/--/-- --/-—/-- 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS 3) establish a base of steady customers? 4 l 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS O--/--/--/--1--/-- - 2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--4 3 6 3 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 MONTHS MO S MONTHS MONTHS / 6 NTH PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE How long does it take a new sales representative in your company to... 4) 5) 6) 7) 8) 150 reach a sales level achieved by most experienced sales representatives in your company? 4 l 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS --2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--4 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 S MONTHS MONTHS 0--/--/--/--1--/--/-- 3 6 9 3 6 MONTHS MONTH use established customers to make new sales contacts? 4 1 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS 0--/--/--/--1--/--/--/--2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--4 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS learn to communicate product information clearly? 4 l 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS --2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--4 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 S MONTHS MONTHS 0--/--/--/--1--/--/-- 3 6 9 3 6 MONTHS MONTH learn to communicate a sales presentation clearly? 4 1 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS 1 -2--/--/—-/--3--/--/--/—-4 0--/--/--/-- --/--/-- 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS to exceed all sales targets and objectives? 4 l 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS 0--/--/--/--1--/--/--/--2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--4 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE 151 How long does it take a new sales representative in your company to... 9) What is your OVERALL estimate of how long it takes a new sales representative in your company to learn how to do their sales job well? 4 l 2 3 OR MORE YEAR YEARS YEARS YEARS 0--/--/--/--1--/--/--/--2--/--/--/--3--/--/--/--4 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 3 6 9 MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS MONTHS PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE 152 SECTION 5 ----------------------- INSTRUCTIONS---------------------------------—- The six questions below also try to get at what you feel is the relationship between pay and performance for sales people in this company. The questions are in a somewhat unusual format. We will be asking you to indicate the probability, or chance in 100, that you will receive XXX dollars of pay annually if you sell XX,XXX dollars of product in a years time. For example, if your company guaranteed you a salary of $15,000 a year plus 10% commission on your sales volume, you would earn $65,000 ($15,000 + $50,000) on sales of $500,000 and would make the following response: If your total annual sales performance was $500,000, what would be your chances (l in 100) of getting paid ..... A) $000.00 per year ........ + B) $05,000 per year ........ + C) $25,000 per year ........ + D) $45,000 per year ........ + E) $65,000 per year ........ + F) $85,000 per year ........ + TOTAL - 100 On the other hand, if you were paid on straight commission and did not receive a guaranteed salary, you would respond differently. If your total annual sales performance was $500,000, what would be your chances (1 in 100) of getting paid ........ A) $000.00 per year ........ + B) $05,000 per year ........ + C) $25,000 per year ........ + D) $45,000 per year ........ + E) $65,000 per year ........ + F) $85,000 per year ........ + TOTAL = 100 Don't worry if the pay and performance figures don‘t match up perfectly. for example, the sales representative on straight commission would have earned $50,000 for the year. Since $50,000 was not listed, the two closest amounts of pay were used: 90 (for a 90% chance) was written next to $45,000 and 10 (for a 10% change) was written next to 65,000. JUST MAKE SURE THAT ALL THE RESPONSES 1N EACH QUESTION 222 12 122. Finally, we have obtained dollar estimates of average, low and high pay, and average, low and high performance for sales representatives in your company. Therefore, the pay and performance numbers used in this part of the questionnaire represent average, low and high pay and performance levels for sales representatives in your company. PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE 153 Chances in 100 of Getting this Annual Pay No A Slight A Fifty-Fifty A good Certain This Chance Chance Chance Chance Will Happen (0) (25 (50) (75) (100) O 10 20 30 4O 50 60 70 80 90 100 Complete each question by placing a number between 0 and 100 on each line. Make sure that the total for each question adds to 100. 1) If your total annual sales performance was $000,000, what would be your chance (1 in 100) of getting paid ........ A) $000.00 per year ........ + B) $05,000 per year ........ + C) $25,000 per year ........ + D) $45,000 per year ........ + E) $65,000 per year ........ + F) $85,000 per year ........ + TOTAL - 100 2) If your total annual sales performance was $220,000, what would be your chance (1 in 100) of getting paid ...... A) $000.00 per year ........ + B) $05,000 per year ........ + C) $25,000 per year ........ + D) $45,000 per year ........ + E) $65,000 per year ........ + F) $85,000 per year ........ + TOTAL = 100 3) If your total annual sales performance was $960,000, what would be your chance (1 in 100) of getting paid ........ A) $000.00 per year ........ + B) $05,000 per year ........ + C) $25,000 per year ........ + D) $45,000 per year ........ + E) $65,000 per year ........ + F) $85,000 per year ........ + TOTAL = 100 PLEASE GO ON TO THE NEXT PAGE 154 Chances in 100 of Getting this Annual Pay No A Slight A Fifty-Fifty A good Certain This Chance Chance Chance Chance Will Happen (0) (25 (50) (75) (100) 0 10 2O 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Complete each question by placing a number between 0 and 100 on each line. Make sure that the total for each question adds to 100. 4) If your total annual sales performance was $1,700,000 what would be your chance (1 in 100) of getting paid ........ A) $000.00 per year ........ + B) $05,000 per year ........ + C) $25,000 per year ........ + D) $45,000 per year ........ + E) $65,000 per year ........ + F) $85,000 per year ........ + TOTAL - 100 5) If your total annual sales performance was $2,440.000, what would be your chance (1 in 100) of getting paid ........ A) $000.00 per year ........ + B) $05,000 per year ........ + C) $25,000 per year ........ + D) $45,000 per year ........ + E) $65,000 per year ........ + F) $85,000 per year ........ + TOTAL - 100 6) If your total annual sales performance was $3,180,000, what would be your chance (1 in 100) of getting paid ...... A) $000.00 per year ........ + B) $05,000 per year ........ + C) $25,000 per year ........ + D) $45,000 per year ........ + E) $65,000 per year ........ + F) $85,000 per year ........ + TOTAL = 100 THANK YOU FOR COMPLETING THIS QUESTIONNAIRE. IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII 11111111111111|11111111111111111111 111911111 11