(1 I: (f! o. I I )9 a! huflrLVn-I.llli 41.}! YO! (ts-tort. ) I: I P!!! I! I ”U“. r-v .01... 1:111:91...”— ' . .n .. v . 3a Ie-IQIIrd-xounlftl firth! tl "U‘vl'gn‘iéo '3 1.2.1116). tr ‘7 'fl 93!..645‘? 1|.li VIII! 50 ‘1' ‘1'.) .9.au5> .cbv’ls. 00...}. no.ri'\1«.9 $3. 0 I v. 101‘ onb‘nh I.al.l. ' lb.‘|;n.u . . .2 eoiv - A... u.‘ 5|!!! mm “WWW! snsm mommies Willi!Ilium Will!!!" 3 00791 4769 LIBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled WHO'S MINDING THE STORE?": DETERMINING THE LOCUS OF CONTROL OF TELECOMMUNICATIONS POLICY MAKING IN THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY presented by Philip C. Fare has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degreein Mass Media 19 November 1992 Date MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 PLACE iN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE MSU is An Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution chS—o: WHO'S MINDING THE STORE?: DETERMINING THE LOCUS OF CONTROL IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS POLICY MAKING IN THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY BY Philip C. Fare A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Ph.D. Program in the Mass Media College of Communication Arts and Sciences 1992 ABSTRACT WHO’S MINDING THE STORE?: DETERMINING THE LOCUS OF CONTROL IN TELECOMMUNICATIONS POLICY MAKING IN THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY BY Philip C. Fare This study explores the locus of control in telecommunications policy making in the European Community (Community). The Community is evolving in terms of economic and international integration from a customs union toward becoming a common market and, eventually, an economic union. The political theories that pertain to international integration--federalism, confederalism, functionalism, neo- functionalism and international regimes--reveal that the Community is currently most like a confederation. The Member States determine policy at the collective level, but retain a large measure of control in implementing that policy at the national level. That control becomes more apparent when the Community's legal order and policy making structure are examined. The Community has its own legal order and policy making processes which involve multiple actors, including the Community institutions, Member State governments and special interest groups. These actors interact in various ways in policy making, depending on the Community agenda and the subject matter involved. The Community has chosen telecommunications as a key industry to lead the Community to economic improvement, recognizing the direct importance of telecommunications in the economy and the derived demand for telecommunications in various industries. However, the telecommunications sector in the Community was operating in a fragmented, heterogeneous market. A series of policy proposals has helped establish the framework for developing a Community-wide telecommunications market in equipment and services. An analysis of the policy making processes that led to those proposals and the Community legal instruments that were later enacted reveals that the national governments retain a large measure of control in determining and implementing Community telecommunications policy. Copyright by PHILIP CLAYTON FARE 1992 To my best teachers and my connection to Europe, my Mother, Gladys, and her parents, Peter and Sarah Banoff ACKNOWLEDGMENTS My greatest thanks go to To. Muth, who eagerly recruited me for the program before either one of us knew what we were getting into, advised and encouraged me along the way and made sure that I finished, all the while allaying my fears, concerns and outright disbelief regarding the vagaries of academia. Without his friendship, respect and guidance I would never have gotten this far. The other members of my committee also share in my thanks: 8d Cohen for advice in broadcasting and statistics, and for staying on the committee long after leaving East Lansing; Todd Simon for sharing legal expertise; and Joe straubhanr for adding to my knowledge of international telecommunications. My first and best teacher, my mother, Gladys rare, also deserves much thanks and love for her spiritual, emotional and financial support during the last three years. She has taught me every important thing I know and instilled in me the faith, hope and work ethic that make accomplishments like this possible. Many friends deserve my thanks for lending a hand, providing encouragement, exchanging ideas or sharing their vi kindness along the way. Jason Butki and Mike voter provided research assistance--as well as Joe Nolan, who helped with the French materials--and showed me how to have fun before, during and after Spartan basketball games. Veronica Gonzales provided sage advice and a shoulder to cry on when I needed it. Rick Bueeelle was always there to do a favor and provide good conversation and laughs. Jeff Kaamiercaak, my cultural mentor, understood best what many others never knew. Cliff Flood was always himself: trustworthy, kind, wise and able to laugh at all my jokes. :Mark.Gieeken.did.more than he knows to help me finish this program by being a good friend. Tony Polley was always witty and provided respite--as well as beats from Collectors 12”, graciously keeping his complaints about the "pop drivel" to a minimum. Stephen Moore kept in touch and kept me in touch with his wealth of knowledge and great ears. Sabrina Sterne-an, poet, goddess and tattoo companion, always shared her insights, laughter and great stories. Brian Kalahan kept me honest and mindful. Chris Cichoeki, though late on the scene, made sure he made his mark, indelibly. Thanks also to MSU football and basketball (for employment and good times), Shawn, Elton, Roddy Frame, Neil Tennant, Chris Lowe, Kirsty MacColl, Mark Wahlberg, Dinah Washington, Mike Scott, and DJ Wayne Miller. Thanks for keeping an eye on me Gareth, like you always do. iAnother life begins today. vii List of Tables List of Figures TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION CHAPTER II THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK A. The Theory of Economic Integration B. Theories of International Integration Federalism Confederalism Functionalism Neo-functionalism International Regimes Conclusion 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. CHAPTER III THE LEGAL ORDER OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY A. Content of Community Law B. Sources of Community Law Treaties Acts of Community Institutions 1. 2. a. b. c. d. e. f. Regulations Directives Decisions Recommendation and Opinions General Requirements for Acts of Community Institutions Institutional and Substantive Rules C. Community Institutions and Community Law D. The Effect of Community Law on National Law E. The Administration of Community Law F. Conclusion viii xi xii 12 13 16 19 25 27 30 33 36 43 44 45 45 47 49 51 52 52 53 55 55 56 60 61 CHAPTER IV INSTITUTIONS AND ACTORS AND THE EUROPEAN A. B. E. COMMUNITY POLICY MAKING PROCESSES Historical Development The Community Institutions 1. Council of Ministers 2. Commission of the European Communities 3. European Parliament 4. European Court of Justice and Court of First Instance 5. European Council 6. Economic and Social Committee Other Actors in the Policy Making Processes 1. Standards Organizations 2. Private Sector Participants Policy Making Processes 1. The Consultation Procedure 2. The Cooperation Procedure 3. Community Legislation After Adoption Conclusion CHAPTER V TELECOMMUNICATIONS AND THE EUROPEAN A. B. C. COMMUNITY ECONOMY European Telecommunications in the 1970s The Dual Role of Telecommunications in the Economy 1. The Direct Role 2. The Indirect Role Conclusion CHAPTER VI DEVELOPING TELECOMMUNICATION POLICY IN THE A. B. C. EUROPEAN COMMUNITY Council Actions November 1984-June 1987 1. Telecommunications Standards 2. Research and Development Programs 3. Procurement Contracts The Green Paper on Telecommunications Implementing the Green Paper 1. Competition in Terminal Equipment 2. Competition in Services 3. Open Network Provision 4. Radio Paging 62 63 64 64 69 75 81 84 85 87 87 89 91 92 98 100 102 108 109 111 112 117 1209 124 125 125 130 132 132 137 137 140 143 145 5. Mutual Recognition of Terminal Equipment 6. Digital European Cordless Telephone D. Conclusion CHAPTER VII CONCLUSION BIBLIOGRAPHY 146 149 150 153 156 LIST OF TABLES Page 1. Telephone Mainlines in the Community--1978-1989 113 2. Telecommunications Investment, 1978-1989 115 116 3. Telecommunications Revenues 1989 xi 1. 2. 3. 4. 6. LIST OF FIGURES Theories of International Integration Directorates General and Special Units of the Commission Standing Committees of the European Parliament Main Stages of the Policy Making Processes Council Actions Taken November 1984-June 1987 Proposed Positions of the Green Paper xii 40 72 79 93 126 136 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION On March 25, 1957, ministers of six European nations met in Rome and signed a treaty (EEC Treatyfi"that created the European Economic Community (EEC), which--together with the European Atomic Energy Community (Euratom)2 and the previously established European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC)3--came to be known as the Common Market or the lTreaty Establishing the European Economic Community, Mar. 25, 1957, 1 Treaties Establishing the European Communities 207 (1987) [hereinafter EEC Treaty]. Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Luxembourg and the Netherlands were the founding Member States. Three of the countries--Belgium, the Netherlands and Luxembourg--had previously formed a customs union on January 1, 1948, known as the Benelux Economic Union, which served as the basis for future discussions regarding establishing the European Economic Community. 2Intended as a means of promoting the peaceful use of atomic energy in Europe, the treaty creating Euratom was also signed by the Community of Six on March 25, 1957. Treaty Establishing the European Atomic Energy Community, Mar. 25, 1957, 1 Treaties Establishing the European Communities 611 (1987) [hereinafter Euratom Treaty]. 3Previously, on April 18, 1951, the Community of Six had signed a treaty establishing the European Coal and Steel Community as a means of promoting economic integration through the common control of the coal and steel industries. Treaty Establishing the European Coal and Steel Community, Apr. 18, 1951, 1 Treaties Establishing the European Communities 17 (1987) [hereinafter ECSC Treaty]. 1 2 European Community (Community) .‘ Motivated by a desire to pool their resources to preserve and strengthen peace and liberty in postwar Europe,’ the signatories established the Common Market to promote "a harmonious development of economic activities, a continuous and balanced expansion, an increase in stability, an accelerated raising of the standard of living and closer relations between the States belonging to it."6 The concept of unifying Europe on economic grounds, however, was not a new one. Following World War I a European federation based on interdependent economies was considered by some as a means to avoid further political anarchy and warn7 Further devastated by World War II, Europeans had begun to question the international political order, in particular the basic unit of that order: the nation-state. European union therefore became not only a means to rebuild Europe's fragmented economy but a way to ‘Although the three Communities retain distinct legal personalities, they were officially merged in 1965, and the designation "European. Community" has since Ibeen. used in official documents, other than legislation, whenever possible and appropriate. Resolution of February 16, 1978 on a Single Designation for the Community (OJ 63, 13.3.1978, p. 36.) 5EEC Treaty, supra note 1, Preamble. 6EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 2. 7See Harold J. Laski, The Economic Foundations of Peace, in The Intelligent Man's Way to Prevent War 502 (Leonard Woolf ed., 1933) 502; Lionel Robbins, The Economic Causes of War 104-09 (1939) . The customs frontier between Belgium and Luxembourg had been abolished on May 1, 1922. control political antagonism. However, despite the shift of economic policy making to the Community level, questions regarding the role of the nation-state in Community affairs remained. The distinctiveness of the Community as an international organization has attracted the attention of various scholars of world politics and political science. Chief among the theoretical schools are federalism, confederalism, functionalism, neo-functionalist and international regimes, all of which differ in their analysis of the role of the nation state in the integrative process.8 As a result several problems arise in reconciling the theories and finding one that adequately describes the Community. Although the theories are each internally cohesive, they differ dramatically from one another, each focusing on different basic concepts. In addition, the theories often tend toward abstraction, focusing on what is presumed will, or ought to, happen within the Community. Finally, at the expense of concentrating on the central institutions that might develop during the integration process, the theories often ignore the status of the nation- state after integration. Over the years the Community has not developed into the 3For a discussion of the various theories of international integration, see Charles Pentland, International Theory and European Integration (1973) ; Stephan Haggard & Beth A. Simmons, Theories of International. Regimes, 41 Int'l Organization 491 (1987). 4 "United States of Europe" envisioned by those theorists who initially studied the organization. Indeed, the Community has developed its own political system and legal order, and its institutions serve as the core of the organization. However, for a number of reasons, those institutions have not developed into the type of supranational entities that people predicted would emerge. Understanding the Community as an international organization requires further understanding of the role of the nation-state in the Community. Throughout the development of the Community its Member States have been at the heart of the integration and policy making processes. At various times for various reasons some Member States have resisted integration on certain levels. The growing membership in the Community,9 which has added to its cultural, economic and geographic diversity, has had an impact on the interrelationship among the Community institutions and the policy making processes. The strict structure of the Treaty of Rome has also been criticized as a hindrance to the development of the competencies of Community institutions beyond a certain point.10 Thus, the 9Since its inception the EC has gradually grown from six to its current twelve Member States. Denmark, Ireland and the United Kingdom became Member States on January 1, 1973. On January 1, 1981, Greece became a Member State. Portugal and Spain became Member States on January 1, 1986. 10See Luciano Bardi & Gianfranco Pasquino, The Institutionalization Process Under the Draft Treaty, in An Ever Closer Union 141 (Roland Bieber et al. eds., 1985). 5 way in which the Member States interact with each other and the Community institutions is important in developing and implementing policy for a unified Europe. Establishing a single market through common policies is a task that begins as the exclusive preserve of the Community and its institutions. The main Community institutions--the Commission, Council of Ministers, European Parliament and European Court of Justice-~each play a different role in the policy making processes. Over the years other institutions and actors--the European Council, the Committee of Permanent Representatives (Coreper) and various standards organizations--have also taken part. As the Community has grown in membership, the competencies of its institutions have changed, bringing about new relationships among themselves and between the organization as a whole and its Member States. In the end, however, it is the Member States that must implement the policies at the national level. Therefore, the locus of control in Community policy making may not be in the Community institutions, for the Member States play an important role through the final stages of the policy making processes. The purpose behind economic integration among the Member States has changed over the years. The economic unity that was once seen as a means to maintain peace and stability is now seen as a means to challenge the economic might of Japan and the United States. This has been true 6 especially since the early 19803, when the Community renewed its focus on developing a single internal market guaranteeing the free movement of persons, goods, services and capital. In 1985, a White Paper identified 300 barriers to establishing a single market and proposed ways to overcome them.11 The next year the Member States signed the Single European Act,12 which took effect on July 1, 1987, and revised the EEC Treaty, implementing the White Paper proposals and changing the decision making processes of the Community institutions. Of particular interest in the Single European Act was a provision that set December 31, 1992 as the deadline for establishing the internal market.‘3 The concentrated effort on economic unity stimulated by the enactment of the Single European Act came none too late. By the mid-19803 the widespread use of new advanced technologies, particularly in the areas of micro-electronics and information technology, had signaled what has been considered the beginning of another long wave of economic development.“ The Community Member States, however, were “Completing the Internal Market: White Paper from the Commission to the European Council, COM(85)310 final. ”Single European Act, 1987 O.J. (L 169). 13Id. art. 13. Although this deadline will not be met in all areas of Community policy, it has served to fecus the Community institutions, the Member States and their citizens on the task of integration. “See, e.g., Chris Freeman, Long Waves of Economic Development, in The Information Technology Revolution 602 (Tom Forester ed., 1985). The Russian economist and statistician 7 suffering from a technology gap and loss of competitiveness in these areas and in telecommunications in general. Behind the technological decline was the fragmented European market, resulting from chauvinistic industrial policies and protective regulatory regimes. Around the same time the Commission acknowledged the two-fold importance of the telecommunications sector in the development of the single market.” First, it recognized the substantial direct role telecommunications plays in the economy through its large contribution to the Community GDP and the large amount of investment it requires.16 Second, the Commission recognized the indirect impact of telecommunications investment, noting the ability of industries such as manufacturing, banking and tourism to increase productivity and decentralize through investing in telecommunications services and equipment.17 Because of the Nikolai Kondrat’ev first measured and noted 50-year cycles of economic development. See Nikolai Kondrat'ev, The Long Wave Cycle (Guy Daniels trans. 1984). Later, Joseph Schumpeter associated the cycles with major technological changes--the introduction of railways, electricity and the development of petroleum chemistry--that spurred further innovations, changes in infrastructure and increased investment. See Joseph A. Schumpeter, Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process (1939). 15Communication from the Commission to the Council on Telecommunications, Progress Report on the Thinking and Work Done in the Field, and Initial Proposals for an Action Programme, COM(84)277 final [hereinafter 1984 Community Action Program]. 16Id. at 3. ”Id. at 3. 8 widespread economic effect of the telecommunications sector as an industry in its own right and as a factor of production for other industries, concerted action by the Member States was determined necessary to face the challenge of the new industrial revolution. The Commission feared that maintaining fragmented national markets and a divided approach to telecommunications policy would only increase the technology gap.18 In June 1987, the Commission issued a Green Paper on telecommunications.l9 The purpose of the Green Paper was to start a Community-wide debate on the future regulatory regime for telecommunications in light of its recognized role in establishing the single internal market. The Green Paper sets out several proposed positions with an aim to improve telecommunications infrastructure, to offer a broader range of services on more favorable terms to users, to ensure coordinated development among the Member States, to create a competitive environment and to ensure a transparent network. Creating a Community-wide telecommunications market necessitates transforming the current situation and changing the regulatory regimes of the Member States. The task "Id . 19Towards a Dynamic European Economy--Green Paper on the development of the common ‘market for telecommunications services and equipment, COM(87)290 final [hereinafter Green Paper]. 9 before the Community requires ensuring that a Community-wide scale and dimension is introduced by the transformation, that no new barriers are created and that existing barriers are removed. To achieve these goals several important directives20 have already been adopted. Most of the directives are aimed at increasing competition in various areas of the telecommunications sector. Three directives have gradually increased competition in the terminal equipment sector, leading to full mutual recognition of terminal equipment.21 Competition in the market for value-added services was opened up immediately in a services directive,22 which also opens up competition in basic data services on January 1, 1993. Telecommunications procurement markets, which had been highly protected by national industrial policies, were opened to bidders from other Member States in a directive ”A directive is one of type of Community legislation. See infra Chapter III. 2‘Council Directive of 24 July 1986 on the Initial Stage of the Mutual Recognition of Type Approval for Telecommunication Terminal Equipment, 1986 0.J. (L 217) 21; Commission Directive of 16 May 1988 on Competition in the Markets in Telecommunications Terminal Equipment, 1988 0.J. (L 131) 73 [hereinafter Terminal Equipment Directive]; Council Directive of 29 April 1991 on.the.Approximation of Laws of the Member States Concerning Telecommunications Terminal Equipment, Including the Mutual Recognition of Their Conformity, 1991 0.J. (L 128) 1 [hereinafter Full Mutual Recognition Directive]. 22Commission Directive of 28 June 1990 on Competition in the Markets for Telecommunications Services, 1990 0.J. (L 192) 10 [hereinafter Services Directive]. 10 dealing with public procurement procedures.23 An Open Network Provision Directive24 concerns the open and efficient access to public telecommunications networks through harmonization of technical interfaces and service features, supply and usage conditions and tariff principles. This dissertation will focus on both the Community and its developing policy in the telecommunication sector as a means to examine several important questions: 1. In light of prevailing theories of international integration, how is the European Community best characterized as an international organization, given the composition and competencies of its institutions? 2. To what extent are the national governments of the Member States involved in the policy making processes? 3. Given the recognized importance of the telecommunications sector in establishing a single internal market, where is the locus of control in the telecommunication policy making process? Chapter II examines the various theories of international integration in an effort to determine their significance in understanding the Community as an 23Council Directive of 17 September 1991 on the Procurement Procedures of Entities Operating in the Water, Energy, Transport and Telecommunications Sectors, 1990 0.J. (L 297) 1. 2‘Council Directive of 28 June 1990 on the Establishment of the Internal Market for Telecommunications Services Through the Implementation of Open Network Provision, 1990 0.J. (L 192) 1 [hereinafter ONP Directive]. 11 international organization. Chapters III and IV provide background on the Community legal order and examine the role of the Community institutions and other actors in the policy making processes. These chapters are necessary to provide a framework for understanding how the Community functions. Chapters V and VI focus on telecommunications policy in the Community. Chapter V discusses the role of telecommunications in the Community in terms of its direct effect on the economy and the derived demand for telecommunications services in various businesses. Chapter VI discusses the approach the Community is taking toward policy making in the telecommunication sector and analyzes the various policy documents issued by the Community, particularly those that implement the objectives of the Green Paper. Chapter VII concludes the dissertation, summarizing the results of the analyses in previous chapters and revisiting the questions proposed in this chapter. CHAPTER II THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK In the varied literature pertaining to international organizations, the Community has been called a strange hybrid.” Its process of integration has been complex, and no single theory has yet established itself in explaining the organization. Indeed, some scholars have criticized the theoretical literature as inadequate in explaining the Community and the relationships that exist between this organization and its member states.26 Some problems in the literature result from theories developed in the early years of the Community that were not later confirmed by the activities of the organization. This chapter will review two major areas of theory that mark the Community as an international organization. First, the theory of economic integration will be discussed in order to determine the status of the Community in its own evolutionary process. Then the various political theories regarding international integration are reviewed to determine which best explains the structure of the Community. 25ShirleyWilliams, Sovereignty and.Accountability in the European Community, 61 Pol. Q. 299, 300 (1990). 26See, e.g., Bardi & Pasquino, supra note 10, at 143; Webb, Carole, Theoretical Perspectives and Problems, in Policy-making in the European Community 1 (Wallace, Helen et al. eds., 2d ed. 1983). 12 13 I. The Theory of Economic Integration The concept of integration involves notions of cooperation and coordination, and integration can occur across various aspects of social, political or economic life.27 For example, a variety of social groups have been brought together through the Community, some bounded by geopolitical frontiers and others not. The Member States have also attempted to further political integration as well, as evidenced by the Treaty of Maastricht.28 The primary impetus for integration, however, has been economic, as evidenced by the objectives stated in the ECSC Treaty, the EEC Treaty, the Single European Act and many of the activities of the organization since its inception. Economic integration, which can occur at various levels, differs from mere coordination or cooperation in that integration involves eliminating certain forms of discrimination.” At the first level is the free trade 27See Gareth Locksley, European Integration and the Information and Communications Technologies: The Double Transformation, in The Single European Market and the Information and Communication Technologies 4-9 (Gareth Locksley ed., 1990). 28See Council of the European Communities & Commission of the European Communities, Treaty on European Union (1992) [hereinafter Treaty of Maastricht]. The Treaty of Maastricht was signed on February 7, 1992 in Maastricht, the Netherlands. 29See Bela Balassa, The Theory of Economic Integration 1-3 (1962); Ali M. El-Agraa, General Introduction 1-2, in The Economics of the European Community (Ali M. El-Agraa ed., 3d ed. 1990). 14 area, an example of which is the European Free Trade Area (EFTA). Within a free trade area the member states lower trade barriers among themselves but remain independent from one another in determining their external trade and economic policies regarding non-members. In the next level, a customs union, external trade policies are harmonized among members. Further advances in economic integration occur at the next levels. When a common market is created, there is free mobility of factors of production, i.e. capital, labor and raw material, between members. The same occurs at the fourth level of integration, the economic union. However, what is added at that level is some degree of harmonization of national economic policies. In a complete economic union, monetary and fiscal policies are unified and subject to a central controlling authority that makes decisions binding on the member states.30 At least one writer argues that these levels each exist separately and are not necessarily stages or parts of a process.31 However, the prevailing view is that the levels are successive.” Economic integration gives rise to an increasing openness and economic interdependence among participating member states, creating its own internal 30Balassa, supra note 29, at 2. 3‘See El-Agraa, supra note 29, at 2. 32.599 T. Hitiris, European Community Economics 1-2 (1988) . 15 dynamic. Independent courses of action become less possible and policy conflicts more apparent as interdependence progresses. Further economic integration becomes a means of resolving such conflicts,33 and progress is made toward the next level. Each level of economic integration allows a variety of possible gains to those nation-states involved. At the level of a free trade area or customs union greater economies of scale can be exploited through the increased size of the market. The larger market can also lead to an improved international bargaining position and improved trade. Competition is also enhanced, forcing changes in economic efficiency. At the level of a common market or economic union additional possible gains include factor mobility, the coordination of monetary and fiscal policies and unified efforts at achieving economic growth.“ Because the Community is evolving, it does not fit easily into one of the levels of economic integration. At its foundation is a customs union.35 However, the institutions within its legal order make decisions binding on the Member States, which is one of the characteristics of 33A move backwards to a lesser level of integration is also possible. However, such a move would seem appropriate only where the need to harmonize policies is minimal and can be achieved through channels other than the economic association itself. 3‘El-Agraa, supra note 29, at 12-13. ”See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 9. 16 an economic union, so an eventual rise to that level seems an apparent secondary objective. At this point in time the Community is a common market, the completion of which is one of the objectives under the Single European Act.36 Various barriers to free factor mobility still exist, such as differing technical standards, which must be lowered to achieve the full status of a common market. Reaching the level of an economic union requires further integration and remains a future goal.37 II. Theories of International Integration Since the inception of the Community several theories-- federalism, confederalism, functionalism, neo-functionalism and international regimes--have been applied to explain the Community.38 Questions regarding the nature of the Community as an international organization are, at their root, theoretical, and the branch of political theory known 36See supra text accompanying notes 12-13. 37See Single European Act, supra note 12, art. 102a. 38Pentland has reviewed federalism, confederalism, functionalism and neo-functionalism as they apply to the European Community. See Pentland, supra note 8. Haggard and Simone have reviewed the various works in the area of internation regimes theory, much of which has been applied to the Community. See Haggard & Simmons, supra note 8. 17 as integration” theory serves as the best means for arriving at an answer. However, for several reasons the literature in this field appears to lack pattern and direction, providing few clear signposts along the way. For the most part the problems arise from the nature of political theory itself, which is often based on a rigid set of assumptions. In addition, the focus of political theory is often normative and predictive. Like most theories, a political theory is a web of interrelated concepts that purports to make sense of the world. Based upon certain definitions, principles and assumptions, a political theory describes, characterizes and explains aspects of political reality through a process of distinction and delimitation. When political theories are based on different premises or use different definitions or take a different perspective on the reality in question, they often contradict one another. This opens them to criticism, which is not uncommon in a field as complex and multifaceted as international politics. The political world is most often explained and understood in theoretical terms rather than through empirical testing. Thus, political theory differs from scientific theory in that it is much harder to assess the 39Political integration has been defined as "the evolution over time of collective decisionmaking among nations." See Leon L. Lindberg, Political Integration as a Multidimensional Phenomenon Requiring Multivariate Measurement, in Regional Integration 45, 46 (Leon L. Lindberg et al. eds., 1971). 18 rigor of a political theory. Because political theories tend to constitute the reality of the political world, there is no independent reality against which they can be judged. One political theory may be discounted on the basis of an assumption of another. Thus, the adequacy of the theory is determined by its ability to explain the political world.‘0 Another problem with political theory is that its focus is often too normative in that in addition to setting forth definitions and principles, it also often sets forth standards and forms of conduct that are desirable. However, any political reality involves certain facts. Theories attempting to describe the Community have often been so absorbed in the normative component that they have ignored the evidence of facts, both present and historical. Their focus has been on what ought to happen rather than on where the Community stands in the logic of international relations. ”See, e.g., Andrew Vincent, Theories of the State 40-42 (1987). 19 A. Federalism Although federalist ideas may have an earlier origin,41 as a modern theory of government, federalism was born to describe the formation of the United States. However, over the years federalist theory has extended its reach and now helps describe a variety of international situations. From the classic theory of federalism new types of federalism have developed that go beyond the model of a unitary system, taking into account the dynamics of international integration. The classic theory of federalism was articulated by K. C. Wheare.‘2 For Wheare, a federal government constitutes ”an association of states, which has been formed for certain common purposes, but in which the member states retain a large measure of their original independence.“3 Power in the association is divided between a general government that is independent of the governments of the associated states and the state governments, which, in certain matters, are independent of the general government. This division of “Some scholars find sources of early federal institutions in the Greek city-states. See, e.g., Adda Bozeman, Politics and Culture in International History 102 (1960) . Other scholars, however, disagree with such characterizations. See, e.g., F. H. Hinsley, Power and the Pursuit of Peace 66-69 (1963). 42See K. C. Wheare, Federal Government (4th ed. 1964). ”Id. at 1. 20 powers is the federal principle, which Wheare defines as ”the method of dividing powers so that the general and regional governments are each, within a sphere, coordinate and independent.”“ Some formal division of powers between levels of government is found in most classic descriptions of federal governments. Macmahon, for example, describes the characteristics of federalism as (1) a distribution of powers between central and local governments, (2) substantial rather than trivial local powers, (3) contact between the central government and individual citizens, (4) some amount of freedom for member states to determine their internal organization and (5) legal equality of the member states.“ Other writers have described federalism as a "constitutional distribution of powers between the central establishment and the members of the system”“ or an ”apportioning jurisdictions among organized collectivities."“ In general, federalists see integration as a political “Id. at 10. 45Arthur W. Macmahon, The Problems of Federalism: A Survey, in Federalism: Mature and Emergent 4-5 (Arthur W. Macmahon ed. 1955). “William Hartwell Bennett, American Theories of Federalism 72 (1964), paraphrasing The Federalist, No. 9, 61 (Alexander Hamilton). 47Marcel Merle, Federalism.and France's Problems with its Former Colonies, 1945-63, in Public Policy 403 (John D. Montgomery and Arthur Smithies eds., 1965). 21 phenomenon involving national political elites. Integration results in a particular kind of supranational entity that deals with the problems of power and control by maintaining order among its member states. Indeed, power is a theme that runs through most federalist writing.“8 The basic objective of federalism is the limitation of centralized power as a safeguard against domination by a single group. Therefore, in a federation a tension exists between unification and pluralism as an attempt is made to balance the advantages of size and uniformity with those of smallness and diversity.‘9 Classic federalism, at a minimum, requires a rigid, formal division of powers between two levels of government. The system is essentially a static one. Political institutions solve problems, often in a mechanistic fashion and subject to various ”checks and balances” to assure a separation of powers. Sometimes there are additional requirements, such as constitutionally prescribed powers and a bicameral legislature. In general, the central government has jurisdiction over defense, finance and foreign relations because these areas demand unitary control to treat problems effectively.” The states retain control over internal affairs. “See Pentland, supra note 8, at 154-55. ”Pentland, supra note 8, at 149, 154. ”Wheare, supra note 42, at 237-39. 22 However, when federalism is applied as a model for international integration, there are fewer requirements.51 Little more is required than two levels of government, each of which is guaranteed autonomy in at least one area of action. For some theorists even such minimal criteria seem inflexible. Trends in international relations since World War II have produced a shift in federalist thinking from a static perspective to one that is more dynamic. Carl J. Friedrich is the principle proponent of a model of federalism in which the concept is construed as a process. Friedrich defines a federation as "a union of groups, united by one or more common objectives, rooted in common values, interests, or beliefs, but retaining their distinctive group character for other purposes.“2 Friedrich's version of federalism is "the process of federalizing a political community" and may result from either integration or differentiation.” He distinguishes federalism from other forms of social organization by its focus on balancing a central organization with its component parts in a process of ”At one time the concept of international federalism was challenged as a misnomer or impossibility. The establishment of the Community, however, has given the term political meaning and significance. See Carl J. Friedrich, Trends of Federalism in Theory and Practice 82-88 (1968). ”Id. at 177. ”Carl. J. Friedrich, Federal Constitutional Theory and Emergent Proposals, in Macmahon, supra note 44, at 514. 23 reciprocal adaptation.“ This approach to federalism focuses more on the process rather than the institutions.” During the 19803 a new approach to federalism developed known as cooperative federalism. This branch of federalist theory is characterized by a shift from the classic distribution of exclusive powers between two levels of government to a model based on concurrent powers.“ This implies a pooling or mixing of competencies between levels of government, changing a dualistically conceived system into a cooperative one. As noted by Levi, an increasing number of policy objectives require the coordinated efforts of both levels of government and a joint commitment to carry them out.” Such joint tasks are characteristic of technical policy areas, according to Bulmer and Paterson.58 Derived in part from the West German experience with federalism,” cooperative federalism turns policy making “Friedrich, supra note 51, at 177. ”According to Friedrich, a federal system can also be found in non-governmental organizations such as unions, interest groups and churches. Id.. “Lucio Levi, Recent Developments in Federalist Theory, in .Altiero Spinelli and Federalism in Europe and in the World 29, 31 (Lucio Levi ed. 1990). ”Id . ”See Simon Bulmer & William Paterson, The Federal Republic of Germany and the European Community 187 (1987). ”See Simon Bulmer & Wolfgang Wessels, The European Council: Decision-making in European Politics (1987); Renate Kunze, Kooperativer deeralismus in der Bundesrepublik (1968) . 24 into an exercise in which decisions important to both the central and state governments are made jointly.60 Regardless whether the approach to federalism is static or process-oriented, several prerequisites are necessary before a federal system of government can be adopted.61 Most important is the requirement that the member states desire to unite under a single independent government,62 without which there cannot be a federal government. At the same time the member states must desire to retain or establish independent local or regional governments for some matters. Otherwise, there would be no division of powers between levels of government. Thus, the member states must desire to unite for some purposes and to remain independent for others. The mere desire to form a federal system, however, is not enough; the member states must also be capable of adopting it. First, there must be sufficient economic resources to operate the central government. Similar economic and political systems between member states are other favorable conditions for adopting a federal government. The degree of similarity necessary is related 60For example, in West Germany the federation and the Lander jointly' determine jpolicy’ in. commonly' planned and financed areas concerned with national importance that require large investments by the L3nder and municipalities. “See, e.g., Amitai Etzioni, Political Unification 14-64 (1965); K. C. Wheare, supra note 42, at 35-52. 62Wheare, supra note 42, at 35. 25 to the objectives behind adopting a federal system. Although similarities in language, culture, religion and race might seem essential for federal integration, history has shown they are usually unnecessary.63 Too much divergence between member states regarding these conditions, however, might decrease the prospects for a federal system. In a federal system the state is a political given, something to be accommodated rather than abolished. During integration the state plays an important role because integration can only be brought about by the states themselves. After integration is complete, the state has its own sphere of jurisdiction, although limits are established within the system to control the states’ powers. Nonetheless, in distinction to some other theories of international integration, in federalism the state is a vital entity that continues as part of the integrated system. B. Confederalism The nature of a confederation, or a confederacy, as a political system is a subject few theorists have studied in depth, although confederations are sometimes dealt with briefly in works dealing with federalism. John C. Calhoun, 63Etzioni, supra note 61, at 22-23; Wheare, supra note 42, at 38-39. 26 the nineteenth century political theorist, described a confederation as allied to an assembly of diplomats, convened to deliberate and determine how a league or treaty between their several sovereigns, for certain defined purposes, shall be carried into execution; leaving to the parties themselves to furnish their quota of means, and to co-operate in carrying out what may have been determined on.“ Beloff similarly defined a confederation as a system in which institutions are set up through which "individual governments, acting on behalf of their own countries, accept certain procedures for arriving at joint decisions which they are prepared to carry out afterwards through their own instrumentalities."“ A treaty is the usual document that establishes a confederation and outlines its procedures for making and implementing decisions. Thus, at its heart a confederation is an alliance for joint decision making that does not infringe on the self-determination of its member states. A confederation is distinguishable from a federation, although the former might be a step in the process toward the latter. In a federation the central power is a genuine government usually established by a constitution. Being a government, it has the power to pass and execute laws. Usually the central government in a federation exercises the “John c. Calhoun, Works 162-63 (R. K. Cralle ed. 1968). “Max Beloff, International Integration and the Modern State, 2 J. of Common Mkt. Studies 52, 58 (1963). 27 power to tax and engages in foreign policy and defense. A confederation does not have any of these powers, and what powers it does have are derived from the governments of its member states and a treaty or agreement ratified by those governments. Furthermore, a federation is an unmediated union created by the people of its member states in which a central government and the governments of the member states are coordinate in their own jurisdictions. A confederation, on the other hand, is a union of member states created through the organs of their respective governments and remains subordinate to those governments.“ Thus, the state retains its identity and power in a confederation. However, in the areas that are the subject matter of the confederation, the state exercises that power as a member of a collective. The confederation is "a profound locking together of states themselves as regards the exercise of fundamental powers"67 and represents something "beyond the normal restricted circle of interstate relations."“ “Id. at 165; see also William Wallace, Europe as a Confederation: The Community and the Nation-State, 21 J. of Common Mkt. Studies 57, 61 (1982); Wheare, supra note 42, at 32. 67Murray Forsyth, Unions of States 15 (1981). “Id. at 4. 28 C. Functionalism The functionalist school constitutes a group of theorists who focus on international organizations and the international world order. Best represented by David Mitrany, the functionalists believe that social structures exist to satisfy the needs of society.69 Because the technological and economic needs of societies have become increasingly international, cooperation on a more international regional or global scale is necessary to solve various problems. Thus, the technological and economic character of societies is an imperative of political change resulting in the founding of international organizations. According to the functionalists, however, international cooperation develops around specific needs. As Mitrany noted, "The essential principle is that activities would be selected specifically and organized separately--each according to its nature, to the conditions under which it has to operate, and to the needs of the moment."70 Thus, there is a one-to-one correspondence between societal needs and structures. An international organization does not develop unless there is a specific need for it or a function it must perform. The nature of that function determines 69See David Mitrany, A Working Peace System (1966); Pentland supra note 8; Leonard S. Woolf, International Government (1913). 70Mitrany, supra note 69, at 70. 29 jurisdiction of the organization and the range of its activities. The result envisioned by the functionalists rarely develops beyond a system of intergovernmental cooperation. That system, however, is elastic, as organizations develop or disband depending on specific needs for them.71 Mitrany sees the basis of the system as a complex, interwoven network of organizations. Some method would develop, perhaps through international planning agencies, to coordinate the efforts of these functional organizations in meeting various societal needs.72 There is little government involvement, however, in this process of policy making through international cooperation. For the functionalists "policy making is not seen in terms of a political process through which conflicts of interest and values are mediated. Instead, it is much more a problem-solving exercise, through which common interests are stressed and status is accorded to 'technical experts’...."73 Thus, functionalists believe the role of national governments or political authority is limited in international organizations. Seeing the nation-state as a ”See James P. Sewell, Functionalism and World Politics 68 (1966). ”See Mitrany, supra note 69, at 72-75. 73Carole Webb, Introduction: Variations on a Theoretical Theme, in Policy-Making in the European Community 9 (Wallace, Helen et al. eds., lst ed. 1977). 30 cause of war and international unrest, the functionalists propose to substitute its role with international organizations and their technical experts." D. Neofunctionalism The neofunctionalist approach to political integration, which developed out of the functionalist school, has been closely associated with the growth and development of the Community as an international organization. The neofunctionalists agree with their predecessors that integration is a process of change but believe that the impetus for change comes not from the functional needs of societies but from political forces such as interest groups, political parties and governments pursuing their own interests. The foundations of neofunctionalist theory are found in the writings of Ernst Haas, long an observer of European integration. Haas defines integration as "the process whereby political actors in several distinct national settings are persuaded to shift their loyalties, expectations and political activities toward a new centre, whose institutions possess or demand jurisdiction over the 74See Mitrany, supra note 69. 31 pre-existing national states."” This shifting of loyalties occurs through a process of conflict resolution; when conflicts develop they are shifted from the level of individual states to the collective level of the central institutions for resolution, thus upgrading such issues to a level of common interest.76 The role of central institutions is crucial in the neofunctionalist process of integration. Integration is advanced as coalitions form among political forces and their tasks become more related to collective interests and decision making. This process occurs as a result of ”spillover," which is a neofunctionalist term that refers to the process whereby members of an integration scheme--agreed on some collective goals for a variety of motives but unequally satisfied with their attainment of these goals--attempt to resolve their dissatisfaction either by resorting to collaboration in another, related sector (expanding the gggpg of the mutual commitment) or by intensifying their commitment to the original sector (increasing the level of mutual commitment) or both.77 As integration advances ”the initial task and grant of powers to the central institutions creates a situation or series of situations that can be dealt with only by further ”Ernst B. Haas, The Uniting of Europe: Political, Economic and Social Forces, 1950-57 16 (1958). 76See Leon Lindberg, Integration as a Source of Stress on the European Community System, 20 Int'l Organization 233 (1966). "Peter Schmitters, Three Neofunctionalist.Hypotheses, 24 Int'l Organization 161, 162 (1964). 32 expanding the task and the grant of power."78 Through this process the central institutions acquire the character of supranationality. The closest the neo-functionalists come to describing the end-product of integration is to say that it results in supranationality, a term that has been misinterpreted over the years.79 For Haas, who introduced the concept, supranationality does not refer to the relationship between Community institutions and the governments of member states. Instead, supranationality is a style of decision making. Haas defines it as "a cumulative pattern of accommodation in which the participants refrain from unconditionally vetoing proposals and instead seek to attain agreement by means of compromises upgrading interests."” The neofunctionalists believe that certain conditions contribute to the successful development of a system of collective supranational decision making via spillover. An established pattern of international interaction among political and bureaucratic elites is essential for further integration. In addition, a complex, interdependent socio- economic system is necessary because such a system requires 78Leon Lindberg, The Political Dynamics of European Integration 288 (1963). 79See Robert O. Keohane & Stanley Hoffman, Conclusions: Community Politics and Institutional Change, 276, 280, in The Dynamics of European Integration (WilliamflWallace ed., 1990). soErnst B. Haas, Technocracy, Pluralism [and the lNew Europe, in A New Europe? 64 (Stephen R. Graubard ed., 1964). 33 a high rate of transactions leading to cooperation on a variety of tasks. Finally, some degree of procedural consensus and some commitment by the member states to long- term goals is necessary for a supranational authority to emerge.81 Whether integration is successful depends on the extent to which the developing central institutions represent the interests of the member states. The role of the nation-state in such a system changes over time. Neofunctionalists view the nation-state as a complex of interests and issue-areas which are identified with the political elites rather than as a monolithic structure. The nation-state performs a whole range of functions, and through spillover any of them might be transferred to the collective decision making process of the central institutions. Thus, the spillover process implies an erosion of the nation-state as its functions are gradually taken over by the central institutions. E. International Regimes International regimes is a macro-analytical approach that has been applied to the study of international relations, mostly in critical reaction to functionalism and 81See Pentland, supra note 8, at 120-122. 34 neo-functionalism.82 International regimes theory seeks to identify central concepts and processes that aggregate discrete behaviors and explain the operation of an entire system. Regime theorists believe that not all international cooperation occurs in formal organizations, which they see as rigid, formal frameworks. For these theorists, a regime is an example of cooperation that exists in a broader context. The concept of what constitutes a regime comes in a variety of forms. Keohane and Nye define it as a "network of rules, norms and procedures that regularise behavior and control its effects."83 Puchala and Hopkins argue that a regime exists wherever there is a pattern of behavior influenced by norms.“ However, the existence of a pattern does not necessarily imply the existence of a regime. 82Another'macro-analytical approach that.has been applied to the Community is systems analysis, in particular the branch developed by Easton to explain political systems. See David Easton, A Systems Analysis of Political Life (1965) . Lindberg has applied Easton’s theories involving internal political relationships and linkages to help explain the decision making process in the Community. See Leon L. Lindberg, The European Community as a Political System: Notes Toward the Construction of a Model, 5 J. of Common Mkt. Studies 344 (1967); Lindberg, supra note 39. However, because that work focuses on the dynamics of the decision making process rather than on the structure of the system it reveals little about the characteristics of the Community' as an international or intergovernmental organization. 83Robert Keohane & Joseph Nye, Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition 19 (1977). “Donald Puchala & Raymond Hopkins, International Regimes: Lessons from Inductive Analysis, in International Regimes 61- 91 (Stephen Krasner ed., 1983). 35 Krasner, therefore, has defined a regime as "implicit or explicit principles, norms, rules and decision-making procedures around which actors' expectations converge in a given area of international relations."” However, despite the acceptance of this general definition, there is disagreement regarding defining its components. Several theorists have commented that the differences between principles, norms and rules are difficult to distinguish.“ Most of the literature involving regimes provides only vague descriptions, if any, regarding how regimes are structured. Regimes are rather fluid, changing over time and sometimes weakening or decaying. At best there seems to be some minimal centralized system of dispute settlement but little organizational structure. Thus, the strength of a regime is measured by the degree to which its members comply with its injunctions.87 Because the existence of a regime is determined on the basis of patterns of behavior rather than by institutional structures, nation-states that are members of a regime have greater autonomy than they do in more structural systems such as international organizations. Regimes theorists believe that although international ”Stephen Krasner, Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables, in Krasner, supra note 84, at 21. “See, e.g., Haggard & Simmons, supra note 8, at 493-94 (1987); Robert Keohane, After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy 58 (1984). ”See Haggard & Simmons, supra note 8, at 496-97. 36 institutions can help foster cooperation, nation-states remain the central, unitary actors in world affairs.88 F. Conclusion The problems with political theory in general89 are evident in the literature of international integration, making it difficult to choose a theory that best describes the Community for several reasons. First, although the theories are internally cohesive, they differ dramatically from one another, each focusing on different basic concepts. Lindberg vividly summed up this problem with the literature: As a contributor to the European integration literature I have more and more come to feel as if I were excavating a small, isolated portion of a large, dimly-perceived mass, the contours of which I could not make out. I know that there are others digging there too, for I can sometimes hear them, but we seldom meet or see each other, and we have seldom organized to combine our efforts. What we see as we confront the ever-growing literature on Western European integration is a multitude of events comprising the total economic, political, social, and intellectual life of six countries and the product of their interactions, and a profusion of theories from a variety of disciplines seeking to order these events and make assertions about presumed patterns of persistence and transformation. But the theories hardly ever confront or complement each other or even appear 88Emil Joseph Kirchner, Decision-Making in the European Community: The Council Presidency and European Integration 26 (1992). ”See supra pp. 16-18. 37 in any clear relationship to each other.90 This state of affairs, however, is not surprising because many of the theories were developed, or first applied in an international context, while the Community was in its early years. During that period there was an abundance of formative theoretical work attempting to explain the organization, some of which was not fully developed or was contradictory. As the Community developed and changed, some of the theories lost popularity that others gained or regained as scholars moved on to find new explanations for the organization. The result is a body of literature that appears somewhat disjointed and difficult to reconcile. Second, a problem with the literature is that most of the theories tend toward abstraction, focusing on what is presumed will, or ought to, happen within the Community. Evidence the Community provides about itself through its legal order and institutions is ignored. Although explanation is not the sole purpose of political theory, the tendency in the literature to emphasize normative aspects often obscures what is actually happening within the Community. Thus, some of the theories have been deemed inadequate when compared to real world events.91 Another problem is that some of the theories focus on 90Lindberg, The European Community as a Political System, supra note 82, at 345. 91See authorities cited supra note 26. 38 only one aspect of the integration process: the creation or development of central institutions. This is understandable since the existence of such entities is evidence of integration. However, there is another equally important part of integration that some of the theories ignore: the status of the nation-state after integration. Even where this is addressed, usually little is said. Finally, as the object of theoretical investigation the Community itself is distinctive among contemporary international organizations, its institutions unique. It has executive capacity and a legal dynamic of its own. Community institutions negotiate trade policies among twelve nation-states and on behalf of the group with the rest of the world. Furthermore, and perhaps most important, the Community is a developing organization, continuously advancing to new stages of integration as barriers between its Member States are lifted. However, although the Community is highly structured, it remains an anomaly, "stronger than a mere international organization, weaker than a state...."92 Despite the problems within the literature, there is some order to the theoretical work in the field. Although as Hoffman has noted, ”a flea-market is not a discipline,"” 92Keohane & Hoffman, supra note 79, at 279. 93Stanley Hoffman, Contemporary Theory in International Relations 7 (1960). 39 when the theories are organized around (1) the nature of the central entity, (2) the power structure and (3) the status of the nation-state, the apparent chaos among them lessens (Figure 1). Their differences become easier to understand, and their static and dynamic features become more apparent. Federalism is the most static approach, with a government as its central entity and a rigid division of power between the central and nation-state governments in which the nation-state government retains exclusive power in certain matters. In cooperative federalism the organization is somewhat less rigid, with the central and nation-state governments cooperating with one another and sharing power in certain areas. The power shifts, however, in confederalism, where the central entity is no longer a government but a collective alliance or union of states subordinate to the governments of the nation-states. The nation-state retains a good deal of power in a confederation because it determines the means of executing and implementing the policies determined by the collective. Those theories that have been traditionally associated with the Community--functionalism, neofunctionalism and international regimes--are less structure-bound and more dynamic than the other theories. In these approaches the central entity is a network or system, sometimes involving technical experts representing the nation-state as in functionalism or a vague, supranational institution that 40 Central Power nation-state Entity Structure status Supranational Rigid State retains PEDERALIBM central division exclusive government between central power w/in and nation-state its own govts sphere COOPERATIVE Supranational Cooperation State shares FEDERALISM central between central power w/ in government and nation-state certain govts spheres CONPBDERALIBM Union of states Union of states State retains or collective or alliance power to alliance subordinate execute to nation-state policies govts FUNCTIONALISM Administrative System of State power network cooperation is limited responsive to between by network community nation-state of technical needs govts experts NBO- Supranational Supranational State power FUNCTIONALISM decision institutions is gradually making with expanding usurped by system powers supranational institutions FIGURE 1 Theories of International Integration 41 gradually usurps responsibilities of the nation-state. The power structure in these approaches varies as well, often determined by the subject matter and purpose of the collective decision making at hand. The status of the nation-state is rarely considered in these approaches, which developed to some extent to explain certain limitations of the nation-state in world affairs. Given this comparison the theory that best explains the Community at this time is confederalism. The various theories of federalism are inappropriate because the Community is not a federation--though it may become one-- because its central institutions lack certain federative powers. Although the institutions have legislative powers, they lack the ability to tax and engage in defense and currently lack the authority to develop foreign policy for the Community. Functionalism and neofunctionalism are also inadequate because they underestimate the power of the nation-state. The governments of the Member States remain heavily involved in Community policy making and retain a large measure of control. Finally, international regimes theory ignores institutions and focuses on patterns of activity and processes within systems. Thus, although international regimes theory might inform the decision making process of the organization, it fails to appreciate the institutional structures inherent in the Community. In this stage in its development the Community is 42 currently most like a confederation. Its work is largely an intergovernmental exercise in establishing a common framework of policy. Within the organization there is a tolerance for national diversity in various standards and practices. Thus, rather than abdicate control to the Community, Member States exercise it more effectively as a collective engaged in joint tasks. This becomes apparent in the legal order of the Community and the organizational structure and competencies of its institutions. CHAPTER III THE LEGAL ORDER OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY As an international organization the Community is unique. It is based on the rule of law, and the acts of its Member States and institutions are subject to judicial review to determine whether they conform to the Treaties that established the organization.“ Community law is a type of international law because its basis consists of treaties concluded between sovereign states. However, it differs from traditional international law in its sources and content.95 Community law has its own distinctive legal order, an "organized and structured system of legal rules, with its own sources, and its own institutions and procedures for making, interpreting and enforcing those rules,”” that contributes much to the nature and identity of the Community as an international organization.” This 9‘See Case 294/83, Les Verts v. Parliament, E.C.R. 1357 (1970). ”See P. J. G. Kapteyn. & P. ‘VerLoren, van Themaat, Introduction to the Law of the European Communities 36-38 (Laurence W. Gormely ed., 2d ed., 1989). 9‘G. Isaac, Droit Communautaire General 111 (1983). 97At least one writer has argued that the legal system of the EC is intrinsically tied to the political philosophy and evolution of the Community. See Joseph weiler, Community, (continued...) 43 44 chapter describes the main features of that legal order. A. Content of Community Law Although Community law is a type of international law, in terms of content Community law differs significantly from most traditional international law. Community law forms a body of internal law common to the Member States rather than a law between the Member States. The substantive core of Community law concerns rules for establishing a single internal market to replace the separate national markets: "The Treaty, by establishing a common market and progressively approximating the economic policies of the Member States, seeks to unite national markets into a single market having the characteristics of a domestic market."98 Thus, in the new market the difference between legal relations that have an international character and those that are internal in nature becomes blurred. Compounding the confusion are the numerous fundamental legal rights, concepts and rules of construction that Community law employs which are not commonly part of ”(...continued) Member States and European Integration: Is the Law Relevant?, 21 Journal of Common Mkt. Studies 39 (1982). 98See, e.g., Case 270/80, Polydor Ltd. et al. v. Harlequin Record Shops Ltd et al., E.C.R. 329, 348 (1982). 45 international law.99 Community law does not consist of mutual rights and duties between the Member States as it would if it were traditional international law. Instead, ”Community law regulates a conglomerate of mutual rights and duties between the Community and its subjects, both Member States and private persons, and between these subjects amongst themselves."100 Furthermore, in addition to employing certain concepts and methods of interpretation used in national and international law, Community law also employs its own principles, including solidarity and unity, to further the goal of integration.101 B. Sources of Community Law 1. Treaties Although the treaties establishing an international organization are the usual source of much international law, in the Community they comprise only one source, albeit an important one. The driving force behind the integration of the Community has been the Treaties that established the organization, in particular the EEC Treaty. That Treaty 99See, e.g., EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 220; Jean- Victor Louis, The Community Legal Order 95-96 (1990); Schermers & Waelbrock, Judicial Protection in the European Communities 25-83 (4th ed., 1987). moKapteyn & van Themaat, supra note 95, at 37. 101See Louis, supra note 99, at 50-56. 46 determines that the organization should be based on a customs unionm and lays out objectives and principles of the organization103 but leaves it to the Community institutions to formulate these objectives and principles into concrete measures. The EEC Treaty also defines the powers and procedures of the institutions,“” including provisions regarding the judicial system and application of Community law.105 The duration of the organization'”‘5 as well as the territorial scope of Community law‘m are also addressed in the Treaty. For the most part the EEC Treaty--supplemented by the ECSC Treaty,“ the Euratom Treaty,” modifications of the Treaties,"° and the accession treaties“‘--provide the 1mEEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 9.; see supra pp. 13-16. ‘mSee id. art. 9-122. ‘“See id. art. 137-198. ‘“See id. art. 164-188. 10“The EEC Treaty "is concluded for an unlimited period." Id. art. 240. This indicates the irrevocability of the Member States' commitment to the organization. See Louis, supra note 99, at 74. ‘mThe Treaty applies to the twelve Member States as well as to some of their territories. EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 227. 108See su t pra no e 3. 109See supra note 2. 1“’See, e.g., Single European Act, supra note 12. ‘"See supra note 9. 47 framework for the organization. At least one writer has referred to these Treaties as the constitution of the 1” although the Treaties merely provide a Community constitutional framework (traité-cadre or traité de procedure) for the Community, comparable to national 1” The constitution of the Community, enabling legislation. as a source of Community law, generally refers to what is known as the primary law of the Community. In addition to the Treaties, the primary law includes certain binding acts and rules of the Community institutions. 2. Acts of Community Institutions Another source of Community law, known as the secondary law of the Community, consists of acts adopted by the Community institutions in order to implement the 114 Treaties. These acts include regulations, directives, decisions, recommendations and opinions. The EEC Treaty 112See Weiler, supra note 97, at 41-42; Cf. Rudolf Bernhardt, The Sources of Community Law: The "Constitution" of the Community, in Thirty Years of Community Law 69 (1983). “3Paul Renter, Organisations Européennes 188 (2d ed. , 1970). ‘“Acts of Community institutions should be distinguished from the acts of various representatives, such as the Coreper. The rules in the Treaties regarding the procedure the institutions must follow in making decisions and their legal effect, implementation and judicial review do not apply to acts of representatives. See Kapteyn 8 van Themaat, supra note 95, at 204-08. 48 specifies the nature and legal effect of these acts and contains rules regarding the publication, entry into force and enforcement of them.” The general provisions, however, contain only a legal definition of the various acts which the Council and Commission can adopt in order to carry out their task "in accordance with the provisions of this Treaty. "“‘ Under the concept of attributed powers the questions as to whether and in what form the Council and Commission can adopt such acts depends on the specific powers conferred upon them elsewhere in the EEC Treaty.m Thus, each act must be attributed directly or indirectly to one or more specific provisions of the Treaty. The distinction between each of the permissible acts is important for several reasons. Different acts have different legal effect. In addition, the rules regarding publication and entry into force vary according to the type of act involved. Finally, the distinction involves different legal protection. When it is difficult to distinguish one act from another, substance rather than form u’EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 189-192. 116Id. at art. 189, para. 1. The list of acts in this article is not exhaustive. There is a residual category of acts under the category sui generis that do not fall within one of the listed categories and usually involve the internal management of the Community. n7See Kapteyn 8 van Themaat, supra note 95, at 112-13. Several articles of the EEC'Treaty provide a basis for acts by the Community institutionsw .See, e.g., art. 8a, 63, 90, 100a, 130g and 235. 49 determines the legal status and effect of an act.”8 Therefore, the various acts are distinguished by their object and content. a. Regulations Regulations are the first act mentioned in the general provisions. A regulation has three characteristic elements: (1) its general application, (2) its binding character in its entirety and (3) its direct applicability to the Member States.119 These characteristics combine to make a regulation "the most complete and effective instrument among the battery of powers" available to the Community institutions.120 A regulation is said to have general application because "it is applicable...to objectively determined situations and involves legal consequences for categories of persons viewed in a general and abstract manner. "‘2‘ Thus, a regulation is impersonal and non-individualized in character. This characteristic helps distinguish a regulation from a decision in terms of legal protection. 118See Kapteyn 8 van Themaat, supra note 95, at 190-91. ‘”EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 189, para. 2. m'See Louis, supra note 102, at 82-83. 121Case 6/ 68, Zuckerfabrik Watenstadt GmbH v. Council, E.C.R. 409, 415 (1968). 50 A regulation is also binding in its entirety. Because it is binding, a Member State that has opposed a regulation during the policy making process cannot fail to apply the regulation when it is entered into force.122 Furthermore, because a regulation is binding in its entirety, a Member State cannot grant exemptions from policies introduced by regulations or otherwise modify them or change their scope unless such a change is provided for in a subsequent regulation.123 Finally, a regulation is directly applicable in all Member States. This means that a regulation has immediate direct effectm when entered into force and becomes part of the national law of all Member States. No national legislation is necessary to transform the regulation into national law. Furthermore, the Member States are prohibited from transforming a regulation into national legislation because to allow otherwise would create uncertainty about the legal nature and effect of the provisions.”5 ‘”See Case 39/72, Commission v. Italy, E.C.R. 101, 115 (1973) (Member States cannot apply a regulation in an incomplete or selective manner) [hereinafter Commission v. Italy]. 123See, e.g., Case 18/72, Granaria, E.C.R. 1163 (1972) (Member State cannot grant an exemption from an import levy introduced by a regulation). ‘“See infra notes 146-50 and accompanying text. ‘”If the Member States were allowed to follow their own implementing procedures regarding regulations, such measures ”would have the result of creating an obstacle to the direct (continued...) 51 b. Directives A directive is another source of Community law. According to the general provisions of the EEC Treaty, "a directive shall be binding, as to the result to be achieved, upon each Member State to which it is addressed, but shall leave to the national authorities the choice of form and method."”6 A directive is an indirect form of law that provides a framework for Member States to follow. Member States, however, are obligated to achieve the specific result of a directive. Although the EEC Treaty leaves a certain amount of discretion to the Member States in implementing a directive, "the freedom left to the member states by Article 189 as to the Choice of forms and methods of implementation of directives does not affect their obligation to Choose the most appropriate forms and methods to ensure the effectiveness of the directives."“" The Commission is responsible for monitoring the Member States to verify that a directive has been properly implemented.128 ‘”(...continued) effect of Community regulations and of jeopardizing their simultaneous and uniform application in the whole of the Community." .See Commission v. Italy, supra note 122, at 114. 126EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 189, para. 9. ‘”Case 48/75, Royer, E.C.R. 497, 519 (1976). ‘”EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 155. 52 C. Decisions Another binding act of the Council and Commission is a decision. According to the EEC Treaty, "a decision shall be binding in its entirety upon those to whom it is addressed.'”” Decisions can be addressed to Member States, firms or individuals,‘” and are the means by which the Community adopts individual administrative acts or applies Community law in specific cases. In cases in which it is difficult to distinguish a decision from a regulation, as a general rule a decision must mention an addressee. d. Recommendations and Opinions The final acts mentioned in the general provisions of the EEC Treaty, recommendations and opinions, are non- binding.131 These acts are allowed in a variety of areas under the Treaty. In general the Commission is granted the broad authority to "formulate recommendations or deliver opinions on matters dealt with in [the EEC] Treaty...if the Commission considers it necessary."I32 Recommendations can also be issued to prevent possible distortions of ‘”Id. art. 189, para. 4. 130’Id. art. 191, para. 2. 131Id. art. 189, para. 4. ‘nrd. art. 155, para. 3. 53 competition,133 and opinions can be delivered to promote close cooperation between Member States in social fields.134 Although these acts are non-binding, they do have legal consequences. If a Member State does not comply does with a recommendation addressed to it regarding distortion, the Commission cannot propose that the Council issue a directive to oblige other Member States to eliminate the distortion.w’ If a Member State fails to comply with a reasoned opinion regarding a breach of obligations under the EEC Treaty, the Commission can refer the matter to the Court of Justice.136 e. General Requirements for Acts of Community Institutions Various general requirements must also be satisfied before any acts by the Community institutions become effective. Regulations, directives and decisions "shall state the reasons on which they are based and shall refer to any proposals or opinions which were required to be obtained 133Id. art. 102. ‘uld. art. 118. ‘”Id. art. 101-102. 136Id. art. 169. 54 pursuant to the Treaty."”7 This requirement makes it possible to determine whether the decision making process required by the Treaties has been properly followed. A violation of this rule is grounds for annulling a contested act.‘38 Certain rules limit the freedom of the Council and Commission to fix the date upon which acts enter into force. Regulations are the only act that must be published to become effective. When finalized, a regulation is published inthemmmgmwmitiesinthe nine official languages of the Community. The regulation takes effect on the date specified in its text or, if no date is specified, twenty days after publication.“’9 Directives and decisions need not be published and take effect when served upon their addressees.“° mId. art. 190. Certain provisions of the EEC Treaty require the Council or Commission to consult the Parliament and the Economic and Social Committee before taking action. See, e.g., id. art. 100. 138Id. art. 173. '”Id. art. 191, para. 1. ‘wId. art. 191, para. 2. Although directives and decisions are often published in the Official Journal of the European Communities, their publication is for information purposes only. See Louis, supra note 99, at 86. 55 f. Institutional and Substantive Rules Both the primary and secondary law of the Community can also be categorized into two groups of rules, institutional and substantive. Institutional rules relate to the institutional structure of the Community and its policy making and administrative functions. Specifically, these rules include provisions regarding the application and revision of the Treaties, the legal personality of the Community and its institutions and the composition and power of the institutions. Substantive rules include rules regulating national policy making by the Member States and their own administrative bodies in various sectors. In addition, substantive law includes rules involving the conduct of legal persons governed by Community law, such as the extensive rules in the area of competition law. C. Community Institutions and Community Law The Community institutions also differ from those of traditional international law. In many international organizations the instruments often do no more than provide a forum for agreement among member states. The procedural or organizational provisions in such organizations are often limited, and international adjudication plays only a small role, if any. The Community, however, is Characterized by 56 extensive organizational and procedural provisions and a refined legal system. The institutions have legal personality, legal capacity and real powersIM1 and engage in autonomous legislative and administrative activities. Furthermore, the Community policy making processes involve more than just representatives of the Member States; persons independent of the Member States and private persons collaborate in the process.“2 D. The Effect of Community Law on National Law In addition to the content and sources of Community law, two related legal doctrines help shape the Community legal order: direct effect“3 and supremacy.” These doctrines, which have been called the "twin pillars of the Community legal system,"“5 both involve the effect of Community law on national law and are fundamental to the legal order of the Community. The doctrine of direct effect deals with the ability of legal persons to rely on a particular provision of Community “‘Case 6/64, Costa v. ENEL, E.C.R. 585, 593 (1964) [hereinafter Costa v. ENEL]. ‘”See Kapteyn 8 van Themaat, supra note 95, at 37-38. ”For a thorough discussion of the doctrine of direct effect see Louis, supra note 102, at 107-35. ‘“Soe id. at 135-57. “’Id. at 107 . 57 law before national courts. In referring to its jurisdiction and the question of direct effect, the Court of Justice has stated that the task assigned to the Court of Justice under Article 177, the object of which is to secure uniform interpretation of the Treaty by national courts and tribunals, confirms that the states have acknowledged that the Community law has an authority which can be invoked by their nationals before those courts and tribunals.“‘ Direct effect, thus, differs from direct applicability, which refers to whether national bodies must take action to give national effect to a provision of Community law. There are also two ways in which direct effect can be applied, vertically and horizontally. When applied vertically, the doctrine involves the right of legal persons to invoke a provision of Community law against governments that have allegedly failed to carry out obligations imposed by Community law. When applied horizontally, both parties involved are legal persons.“7 The doctrine of direct effect can be invoked in situations involving Treaty provisions, regulations, decisions and directives. Not all Treaty provisions, however, give legal persons directly effective rights; purely procedural obligations of Member States that involve l“Case 26/62, NV Algemene Transport--en Expeditie Onderneming Van Gend en Loos v. Nederlandse administratie der belastingen, E.C.R. 1, 12 (1963) [hereinafter Van Gend 8 Loos]. ‘”See Louis, supra note 99, at 113. 58 the exercise of discretion by Community institutions or 3 Regulations Member States are not directly effective.“ are directly effective because of their nature, and function as a directly applicable source of Community law.“9 Although directives and decisions have no direct applicability by virtue of the EEC Treaty, the Court of Justice has held that they have vertical direct effect.”0 The supremacy of Community law refers to the fact that Community law is "an integral part of, and take[s] precedence in, the legal order applicable in the territory of each of the Member States."”‘ Adthough there is no specific supremacy provision in the Treaties, the Court of Justice has further confirmed this principle by reference to the EEC Treaty provision designating regulations as binding and directly applicable in all Member States: "[TJhis provision, which is subject to no reservation, would be quite meaningless if a State could unilaterally nullify its effects by means of a legislative measure which could ‘“See Costa v. ENEL, supra note 141, at 595-96 (1964). 149See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 189, para. 2; Case 43/71, Politi, E.C.R. 1039, 1048 (1971). 1”See, e.g., Case 9/70, Grad, E.C.R. 825, 837 (1970) (involving the direct effect of a directive); Case 33/70, SACE, E.C.R. 1213, 1223 (1970) (involving the direct effect of a decision). 1“Case 106/77, Simenthal, E.C.R. 629, 643 (1978) [hereinafter Simenthal]. 59 prevail over Community law."‘52 Thus, supremacy is linked to both direct applicability and direct effect. The doctrine of supremacy is applied by the courts. Unconditional and absolute, the doctrine applies to any national law, even a constitutional principle.”3 To allow otherwise would disrupt the Community and the process of integration. Without common rules and procedure there cannot be a Community, and there cannot be common rules if Community law is subject to national laws and rules that vary from one Member State to another. The doctrines of direct effect and supremacy shed light on the effect of Community law on national law and the relationship between the Community and national legal systems. Unlike in other legal systems with similar concepts, the Community and national legal systems are not in a dualistic relationship, but a cooperative one. This relationship has been best summed up by the Court of Justice: "Every national court must, in a case within its jurisdiction, apply Community law in its entirety and protect rights which the latter confers on individuals and must accordingly set aside any provision of national law 152See Costa v. ENEL, supra note 141. 1”Where the application of the doctrine of supremacy is not so»clear is in.cases involving conflicts between Community law and later national legislation. 'The highest courts in.the six original Member States have all recognized the supremacy of Community law in such cases. The issue has not been directly addressed in the other Member States. See Louis, supra note 99, at 149-57. 60 which may conflict with it, whether prior or subsequent to the Community rule."“4 E. The Administration of Community Law The EEC Treaty requires that Member States take appropriate measures to fulfill their obligations arising under the Treaty and from actions taken by Community institutions.” Although the Member States have some discretion in carrying out this task, their autonomy is not absolute. Member States are obligated to administer ‘“ ensuring uniformity, supremacy Community law properly, and the direct effect of Community law. Implementing Community law on a national basis--except in cases of directly applicable acts, which need no national implementation--often involves amending existing legislation or enacting new legislation. Various branches of national governments have been involved in performing this task, depending on the governmental organization of the Member States and the nature of the legislation required. In any case, however, the Commission is responsible for monitoring how Member States comply with their obligation to implement Community law. l“See Simenthal, supra note 151. 1”EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 5. 1“‘Id. para. 2. 61 F. Conclusion The Community legal order distinguishes the Community from other international organizations. Through laws developed in the Community system, a common, uniform set of rules is promoted throughout the Community. The way those rules are developed is an integral part of the Community legal order and involves a variety of actors and policy making processes. CHAPTER IV INSTITUTIONS AND ACTORS AND THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY POLICY MAKING PROCESSES In the Community the task of establishing the single market is a complex one that involves multiple actors. Chief among them are the Community institutions, which embody the character of the Community as an international organization and represent it as a visible entity to its members and the outside world. The primary institutions-- the Council of Ministers, Commission of the European Communities, European Parliament and the Court of Justice-- provide the Member States forums for determining, expressing and implementing policy.”’ However, those institutions do not act alone. Various secondary institutions and actors associated with European regional, national and public interests are also involved in the policy making processes. This chapter reviews the Community institutions and other actors involved in policy making and the processes in which they engage to determine policies for the single market. ls"Roland Bieber, The Institutions and Decision-making Procedure in the Draft Treaty Establishing the European Union, in An Ever Closer Union 31 (Roland Bieber et al. eds., 1985). 62 63 A. The Historical Development The roots of the Community institutional framework are found in the ECSC, the first of the European Communities. The ECSC Treaty created four central institutions--the High Authority, Common Assembly, Council of Ministers and Court of Justice--each with its own composition, functions and Character.“ These institutions not only distinguished the ECSC from other international organizations that existed at the time, but provided a framework that the other Communities, the EEC and Euratom, would later adopt. When the EEC and Euratom were established in 1957, they too created a similar framework of four central institutions, although the EEC and Euratom Treaties substituted a Commission for the High Authority of the ECSC.”9 Over the years several modifications have occurred in the institutional organization of the Community. In 1965, a treaty was signed that established a single Council of Ministers for all three Communities and merged the High Authority of the ECSC and the EEC and Euratom Commissions into one Commission.‘°° The Communities themselves, l5"See ECSC Treaty, supra note 3, art. 7-45. ‘”See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 4; Euratom Treaty, supra note 2, art. 3. “o‘rreaty Establishing a Single Council and a Single Commission of the European Communities, Apr. 8, 1965, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1 Treaties Establishing the European Communities 823 (1987 [hereinafter Merger Treaty]. 64 however, still remained distinct entities. In addition, a Committee of Permanent Representatives (Coreper) was established as a subsidiary body of the Council.”1 Years later the Single European Act altered certain aspects of the decision-making system to help accelerate Community integration.“52 Despite these changes, however, the same basic institutional arrangement created in the 1950s still exists in the Community today and remains at the center of policy making. B. The Community Institutions 1. Council of Ministers The Council of Ministers (Council) is the main decision making institution. According to the Merger Treaty, the Council "shall consist of representatives of the Member States. Each Government shall delegate to it one of its members.“53 .Although this prescription makes it seem as though there is only one Council, the exact representatives vary according to the policy task at hand. Thus, there are actually several Councils. The General Council deals with general issues regarding policy coordination, with external 1“Although the Coreper has existed since 1958, it was first legally recognized in the Merger Treaty. See id. art. 4. 162See infra. 163Merger Treaty, supra note 160, art. 2, para. 1. 65 relations and with politically sensitive issues. Sectoral matters, such as energy, agriculture and the environment, are handled by the Technical Councils. Choosing Council representatives is in the discretion of the Member States, and usually the foreign minister of their ministry of state sits on the General Council. Other ministry representatives often sit on the Technical Councils. At most Council meetings--there are approximately ninety each year-- representatives are accompanied by small national delegations and support teams.“‘ The Council is assisted by the Coreper, whose members are ambassadors who head the Permanent Representations of each Member State to the Community. Established under the Merger Treaty, the Coreper prepares the work of the Council and carries out any tasks assigned by the Council,“” The Coreper, however, is a subsidiary body of the Council and does not have independent decision making powers. As ambassadors to the Community, the members of the Coreper form important links between Member State governments and the Community institutions and provide an important means 16‘See Kapteyn 8 van Themaat, supra note 95, at 103-08. 1“Merger Treaty, supra note 160, art. 4. The Coreper is divided into the Coreper I, whiCh is comprised of deputies from each permanent representation and handles technical matters, and the Coreper II, which is comprised of the Permanent Representatives themselves. Juliet Lodge, EC Policymaking: Institutional Considerations, in The European Community and the Challenge of the Future 26, 45-46 (Juliet Lodge, ed. 1989). 66 for testing Member State reactions to Community policy proposals. Meetings of the Council are generally convened by the Council President,“ an important position that rotates every six months, Changing in January and July. The rotation is based on strict alphabetical order according to how the Member States spell the name of their country in their own language. Because responsibilities vary between the first and second half of the year, pairs of countries will reverse their order after the current rotation is completed at the end of 1992. Thus, Denmark will hold the Presidency for the first half of 1993 and Belgium for the second half.“7 Holding the Council Presidency provides both advantages and disadvantages.16$ Although the position has several tasks and enjoys certain privileges, there are no executive powers associated with it, such as vetoes or sanction possibilities. The Council President is responsible for arranging and chairing all Council meetings, which gives the President control over not only the agenda and but how often the General and Technical Councils meet. In addition, the President takes the lead in building a consensus for policy 166See Merger Treaty, supra note 160, art. 7. 167Id. art. 7; See also, Neill Nugent, The Government and Politics of the European Community 125 (2d ed., 1991). ‘“For a detailed analysis of the Council Presidency, see Kirchner, supra note 88. 67 initiatives and development and represents the Council before other Community institutions. These responsibilities allow the President some influence in the nature of debate and the timing of the adoption of legislation. That influence, however, is somewhat tempered by the coordination and cooperation between the preceding, the incumbent and the succeeding Presidencies.169 In addition to the influence a Council President can exert, a certain amount of prestige and esteem attaches as a result of the position, particularly when a Presidency has been successful. Bad reviews, however, can follow a bad Presidency. A distinct disadvantage of the position is the heavy workload which poses an administrative burden for any Member State, especially the smaller ones, who often find the task difficult to handle. In the EEC the primary duty of the Council is to ensure the coordination of the general economic policies of the Member States.”° Although the Council President organizes an agenda, the Council generally acts only on proposals made by the Commission. The Council can, however, initiate 169See Nugent, supra note 167, at 104-05. ‘mEEC Treaty, art. 145. In the ECSC the primary duty of the Council is "to harmonize the action of the High Authority and that of the Governments, which are responsible for the general economic policies of their countries. See ECSC Treaty, supra note 3, art. 26, para. 1. In Euratom the primary duty of the Council is "to coordinate the actions of the Member States of the Community.” See Euratom Treaty, supra note 2, art. 115, para. 2. 68 policy by ”request[ing] the Commission to undertake any studies the Council considers desirable for the attainment of the common objectives, and to submit to it any proposals."171 The Council has also been granted attributed powers under the Treaties to make decisions that are legally binding upon the Member States and subjects of the Community.”2 After deciding the essential elements and rules of an area to be regulated, the Council may "confer on the Commission, in the acts which the Council adopts, powers for the implementation of the rules which the Council lays down. "‘73 However, the regulatory power of the Council may not be delegated in its entirety to the Commission since that would require the Commission to implement the rules of the Treaty itself, rather than merely the rules laid down by the Council. The Council performs various organizational functions in the Community besides its legislative function. For example, the Council ultimately determines the rules governing the committees provided for by the EEC Treaty.174 The Council also has the power to determine aspects of the organization of the Court of Justice, including the number ‘"EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 152. 172See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 145. I73EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 145. ‘uId. art. 153. The Council determines those rules after receiving an opinion from the Commission. Id.. 69 of judges sitting on the Court.”5 In addition, the Council also can alter the size of the Commission”5 and determine the salaries the Commission members and judges.177 The Council is the one Community institution in which the national governments of the Member States are represented as such. This intergovernmental arrangementI78 brings a strong nationalistic character to the debates and work of the Council, making it the forum where Member States can exert their individual power as nation-states in the policy making processes. However, because the ability to compromise is necessary for successful policy making, the Council also provides a forum for developing mutual understanding between Member States. 2. Commission of the European Communities The Commission of the European Communities (Commission) bears its own political responsibility in the Community and ‘PId. art. 165. 17“Merger Treaty, supra note 160, art. 10(2). ‘Wrd. art. 6. ‘flAlthough the Council is intergovernmental in nature, the work of the Council is unlike the work of other intergovernmental organizations in that it does not result in international agreements among the Member States. Instead, the acts of the Council have legal effect under the Treaty and are subject to review by the Court of Justice. See supra pp. 46-53. 70 differs in several ways from the Council. The Commission itself consists of "seventeen members, who shall be chosen on grounds of the general competence and whose independence is beyond doubt."‘79 The larger countries in the Community- -France, Germany, Italy, Spain and the UK--appoint two members to the Commission, often attempting to reflect the political interests at home.“° The remaining smaller Member States each have one seat on the Commission. The members of the Commission are appointed by the common accord of the Member States to four-year terms."“ A President is also appointed in the same manner.182 Supporting the Commissioners is a staff of approximately 16,000 officials and temporary agents.183 The hierarchical structure of the Commission is complex, and lines of authority are sometimes blurred. The various policy portfolios are distributed among the Commissioners, who carry the main leadership responsibility 179Merger'Treaty, supra note 160, art. 10(1) as amended.by Act of Accession ESP/PORT, art. 15. 180For example, the United Kingdom has thus far appointed both a Conservative and a Labour Party representative to the Commission. See Kapteyn 8 van Themaat, supra note 95, at 108, n. 28. mMerger Treaty, supra note 160, art. 11. Although Commissioners are appointed, they are nominated by the Member State governments. '“Id. art. 14. 183Richard Hay, The European Commission and the Administration of the Community 31 (1989). 71 in that particular area.134 The policy development work itself is divided into separate areas that are handled by twenty-three different Directorates General (DG) which vary in size and internal organization‘” (Figure 2). The head of each DG reports directly to the Commissioner in charge of its policy portfolio. One of the primary functions of the Commission is to initiate the policy making processes in the Community.186 Under the EEC Treaty the Commission is required to "formulate recommendations and deliver opinions on matters dealt with in this Treaty, if it expressly so provides or if the Commission considers it necessary."187 Other treaty provisions make it clear that in most cases the Council can act only after receiving a proposal from the Commission.‘“ The Commission is aided in this process by the various Directorates General and a network of advisory “‘For a discussion of the portfolio system, see Peter Ludlow, The European Commission, in The New European Community: Decisionmaking and Institutional Change 85, 88-93 (Robert O. Keohane et al. eds., 1991). 185Each DG is generally referred to by its number, rather than its area of expertise, such as DGXIII, which is in charge of telecommunications, information technologies and innovation. 186The Commission, however, does not have a monopoly on initiating policy in the Community. See infra text accompanying notes 250-252. '"EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 155. 1“See, e.g., id. art. 28 (free movement of goods); art. 63 (free movement of services). 72 MW DGI External Relations DGII Economic 8 Financial Affairs DGIII Internal Market 8 Industrial Affairs DGIV Competition DGV Employment, Industrial Relationships 8 Social Affairs DGVI Agriculture DGVII Transport DGVIII Development DGIX Personnel 8 Administration DGX Information, Communication 8 Culture DGXI Environment, Nuclear Safety 8 Civil Protection DGXII Science, Research 8 Development DGXIII Telecommunications, Information Industries 8 Innovation DGXIV Fisheries DGXV Financial Institutions 8 Company Law DGXVI Regional Policies DGXVII Energy DGXVIII Credit 8 Investments DGXIX Budgets DGXX Financial Control DGXXI Customs Union 8 Indirect Taxation DGXXII Coordination of Structural Policies DGXXIII Enterprise Policy, Distributive Trades, Tourism 8 Social Economy MW Secretariat General of the Commission Legal Service Spokesman's Service Translation Service Joint Interpretation 8 Conference Service Statistical Office Consumer Policy Service Joint Research Center Task Force "Human Resources, Education, Training 8 Youth" Euratom Supply Agency Security Office Office for the Official Publications of the European Communities Figure 2 Directorates General and Special Units of the Commission 73 and consultative committees. The Commission also performs several executive functions that closely involve it in the implementation, supervision and management of Community policies. Under the Treaties the Council may confer powers upon the Commission to implement rules laid down by the Council.189 These delegated rule-making powers include not only the application of rules, but also their elaboration. The Council, however, does not delegate this regulatory power completely to the Commission because the rules laid down by the Council are usually drafted with great detail.190 The Commission may also delegate some of its rule-making duties to individual members and senior officials who act in the name of the Commission and take into account its principle of collective responsibility to the Community.”‘ The supervisory function of the Commission includes overseeing that Member States fulfill their obligations under the Treaties and Community legislation.192 The front- line implementation of Community policy is generally ‘”Id. art. 155. ‘wFor a discussion of the delegation of powers between the Council and the Commission, see Kapteyn and van Themaat, supra note 95, at 119-23. 191See Rules of Procedure of the Commission, art. 27, 1975 0.J. (L 199) 43. 192EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 155. 74 delegated to the appropriate national agencies in the Member States. Then, as part of its obligation to prepare an annual report regarding Community activities,‘93 the Commission attempts to assure that Community duties are properly performed at the national level. This task presents several difficulties to the Commission. At times a Member State may be unwilling or unable to implement Community policy, and the limited resources of the Commission can make infringements difficult to detect.194 When the Commission becomes aware of possible infringements, it informs the Member States involved, conducts investigations and delivers an opinion. Should the infringement continue, the Commission can bring the matter before the Court of Justice.”5 Finally, as part of its executive function the Commission helps manage aspects of Community finances. The duties of the Commission in this regard on the revenue side include making sure that the correct rates are applied 193The Commission must present its annual report to the European Parliament. See Merger Treaty, supra note 160, art. 18. 194The Commission obtains the necessary information to perform this supervisory function primarily from the Member States, which are often required to report back to the Commission regarding the methods of implementing the results desired in directives. In addition, Member States are obliged under the Treaties to facilitate the achievement of the Community's tasks. See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 5, para. 1. This obligation includes complying with requests for information from the Commission. 1951d. art. 5, para. 2. 75 within categories of revenue and that proper payments are made to the Community by the Member States.“5 On the expenditure side the Commission oversees the general operation of the Community to assure that it remains within the approved annual budget.”7 The character of the Commission as a Community institution differs greatly from that of the Council. Unlike the Council, whose members represent the interests of the individual Member States, the Commission represents Community interests as a whole. The members of the Commission are required to maintain their independence and "neither seek nor take instructions from any Government or from any other body. "1” Thus, the Commission complements the nationalistic character of the Council and remains in a close, interdependent relationship with it. 3. European Parliament The European Parliament (Parliament), originally called the Assembly,‘99 consists of "representatives of the peoples 196See id. art. 201. mSee id. art. 205; Nugent, supra note 167, at 79-82. ‘”Merger Treaty, supra note 160, art. 10(2). 199In 1962, the Assembly adopted.the "European Parliament" as its title. See 1962 J.O. (1045) 62. 76 of the States brought together in the Community...."200 Persons who are members of the Parliament represent the peoples of the Community collectively. The use of the phrase ”peoples of the States" rather than "peoples of the Member States" in the Treaty reinforces the collective nature of that representation. Thus, the members of Parliament do more than represent the people of an individual Member State; they represent all the peoples of the Community. Currently there are 518 members of Parliament.201 ‘The number of members from each Member State varies on the basis of population.202 Although members of Parliament can also hold seats in a national parliament, holding other positions in Member State governments or being a member or active official in any other Community institution is prohibited.203 Members of Parliament are currently elected for five-year terms. Although members of Parliament were at one time 2""EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 137. 201Id. art. 138(2) . 202Currently, the number of seats is distributed as follows: Germany, France, Italy and the UK each have 81; Spain has 60; the Netherlands has 25; Belgium, Greece and Portugal each have 24; Denmark has 16; Ireland has 15 and Luxembourg has 6. Id. art. 138(2). 203See Act Concerning the Election of Representatives of the Assembly by Direct Universal Suffrage, art. 6(1), 1976 0.J. (L 278) 1 and 5 [hereinafter Act on Direct Elections]. 77 appointed, direct elections have been held since 1979.”” However, no uniform electoral system is prescribed by the Act on direct elections. Until a uniform procedure can be agreed upon by the Member States, elections are governed by national provisions.”” .At present each Member State, as well as Northern Ireland, has its own election procedure.206 Despite the problems that arise given the different proceduregmn the advantage of having direct elections is that they allow voters to air views on Community policy. However, for many voters the Parliament remains a distant Community entity . 2°“ The Parliament is organized around partisan politics, and political groups form around ideological identification and political family traditions.209 Since the 1989 elections there have been ten political groups in 20‘Thetmethod of appointing members was intended.under the Treaties as temporary. See, e.g., EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 138(3). 20SSeeAct on Direct elections, supra note 203, art. 7(2). 2mSee Nugent, supra note 167, at 142-45. 20”To date there have been three elections--in 1979, 1984 and 1989. Each election has been contested on the basis of different national election procedures. See id. at 142. 208Light voter turnout is often mentioned in regard to Parliament elections. In 1979, only 62.5% of those persons eligible to vote did so. In 1984, the turnout was 59%, and in 1989 57.2%. See Francis Jacobs 8 Richard Corbett, The European Parliament 25 (1990). 209The requirements for forming a political group vary depending on the number of Member States involved. See Parliament's Rules of Procedure. 78 Parliament.‘no Each group receives funds for administrative and research purposes, including non-attached members, who are regarded as a group for this purpose. In addition, the political groups are guaranteed representation on Parliamentary committees and speaking rights in plenary sessions. Much of the work of the Parliament is carried out by its standing committees, of which there are currently eighteen (Figure 3).2n Ad hoc committees are established to investigate special topics asrequired. The political groups negotiate committee memberships so as to ensure fair representation of the Member States and of political views. Most members of Parliament are on at least one standing committee. The Parliament performs both advisory and supervisory functions that are conferred upon it by the Treaties.212 Consultation of the Parliament is often required before the Council can act. However, the Council often seeks the opinion of the Parliament when not required to do so, and the Parliament sometimes addresses opinions on its own initiative to the Council. Although the Treaties require 210For a detailed discussion of the political groups, their membership and their ideology, see Jacobs 8 corbett, supra note 208, at 54-83; Nugent, supra note 167, at 146-53. 2“For a detailed discussion of the Parliamentary committees, see Jacobs 8 Corbett, supra note 208, at 91-124. 212See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 137. 79 Committee Title # of members 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. Political Affairs Agricultural Fisheries 8 Rural Development Budgets Economic 8 Monetary Affairs 8 Industrial Policy Energy, Research 8 Technology External Economic Relations Legal Affairs 8 Citizens's Rights Social Affairs, Employment 8 the Working Environment Regional Policy 8 Regional Planning Transport 8 Tourism Environment, Public Health 8 Consumer Protection Youth, Culture, Education, Media 8 Sport Development 8 Co-operation Budgetary Control Institutional Affairs Rules of Procedure, the Verification of Credentials 8 Immunities Women's Rights Petitions Figure 3 56 47 32 52 34 29 34 41 38 30 51 31 43 28 38 27 33 25 Standing Committees of the European Parliament 80 only the Council to consult the Parliament on policy proposals, the Commission also consults the Parliament on occasion. The primary supervisory power of the Parliament over the activities of the Community is its power to dismiss the Commission en bloc by adopting a motion of censure.213 In addition, however, the Parliament maintains a dialogue with the Commission, reviewing Community affairs through a variety of procedures. The Commission is required to respond to questions put to it by the Parliament or its individual members.“ The Parliament also holds public deliberations regarding the annual report on Community activities submitted to it by the Commission.”5 iFinally, the Parliament has considerable power regarding the budget of the Community through its requisite approval of the overall budget and overseeing all non-compulsory expenditure, certain Community development projects and its own administrative budget.216 213EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 144. Although a motion to censure has occasionally been tabled, none has ever been approved. See Kapteyn 8 van Themaat, supra note 95, at 138. 2MEEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 140, para. 3. The ECSC Treaty require the High Authority to respond to questions from the Parliament" See ECSC Treaty, supra note 3, art. 23, para. 3. 21‘See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art 143. 216See id. art. 203. 81 In distinction to other Community institutions the Parliament is characterized as the representative body of the peoples of the Community. It maintains this role by organizing itself around Community-level political groups rather than national alliances. Although its role in Community policy making is somewhat limited, its powers are nonetheless important. Its supervisory powers over the Commission provide a crucial check in protecting collective Community interests, and its control over the Community budget gives it influence over the general direction of policy making efforts in the Community. 4. European Court of Justice and Court of First Instance The European Court of Justice (Court of Justice) consists of thirteen judges,"7 who are assisted by six 218 advocates-general. Both positions last for a renewable 9 Every three years there is a partial term of six years.” replacement of the members of the Court of Justice, and seven or six judges and three advocates-general are replaced 2"’Id. art. 164, as amended by Act of Accession ESP/PORT, art. 17. 218Id. art. 166, para. 1, as amended by Act of Accession ESP/PORT, art. 18. 2"Id. art. 167, para. 1, as amended by Act of Accession ESP/PORT, art. 19. 82 alternatelyfi220 Although the judges and advocates-general are supposed to be appointed by common accord of the governments of the Member States,”1 this does not happen in practice. Each Member State nominates one judge, leaving the thirteenth judge to be appointed by common accord.222 The appointment of the advocates-general tends to be more collective than that of the judges, although the larger Member States are usually able to ensure that they each have one of the positions.223 Behind the scenes a staff of approximately 650 handles the administrative work and provides language services.”‘ It is the duty of the Court of Justice to "ensure that in the interpretation and application of the Treaty the law is observed.”225 The Court of Justice performs this duty through its judgments in direct actions usually involving the failure of Member States, the Council or the Commission 220Id. art. 167, para. 2, as amended by Act of Accession ESP/PORT, art. 19. 22‘l'd. para. 1, as amended by Act of Accession ESP/PORT, art. 19. 222Office for the Publications of the European Communities, The Court of Justice of the European Community 3 (1986). 223See Nugent, supra note 167, at 188. 22‘Id. 22‘Id. art. 164, as amended by Act of Accession ESP/PORT, art. 17. 83 to fulfill their Community obligations226 or the legality of acts of the Council or Commission.227 The Court of Justice also has jurisdiction to issue preliminary rulings concerning points of Community law to enable courts in the Member States to give judgements in cases they are hearing.228 Because of the increasing case load before the Court of Justice, the Council was given the power to establish a Court of First Instance.229 The Court of First Instance was established in November 1989 and has twelve judges but no advocates-general. It hears only disputes between the Community and its staff, actions brought against the Commission under the ECSC Treaty and certain cases involving the Community competition rules. The Court of Justice hears all other cases. Decisions of the Court of First Instance can be appealed to the Court of Justice. The Court of Justice and Court of First Instance play an important role in establishing the legal order of the Community. The courts are the source of uniform interpretation of Community law throughout the Member States. Without these independent institutions to give 226See id. art. 169-70, 175. 227See id. art. 173. 228See id. art. 177. 229See id. art. 168a, as amended by Single European Act, supra note 14, art. 4. 84 rulings regarding legal obligations under the Treaties and Community legislation, Community decision making would be less effective and establishing common policies throughout the twelve Member States would be more difficult. 5. European Council The European Council is a body consisting of "the Heads of State or Government of the Member States and the President of the Commission...assisted by the Ministers for Foreign Affairs and by a Member of the Commission."230 The European Council meets twice each year“ on a relatively informal basis. While it does not participate in the formal policy making processes of the Community, its exchange of ideas gives general direction to Community policy development232 and assures progress and overall consistency in Community activities. The general economic situation in the Community and progress toward the completion of the internal market are usually on the agenda at European Council meetings. Other areas of activity include economic and monetary integration, external trade issues, external 230Single European Act, supra note 12, art. 2. 2“my. 232For example, the European Council has played a significant. role in introducing’ direct. elections in ‘the Parliament and in Community expansion. See Kapteyn & van Themaat, supra note 95, at 107. 85 international political issues and Community political integration.233 However, because there are no Treaty provisions setting out the responsibilities of the European Council, it has relative freedom in the activities it chooses to undertake. The main effect of creating the European Council has been to increase the influence of the Member States in the Community policy making processes. The European Council has become a forum for initiating policy and mediation, thus undermining some of the power of the Commission in these areas. In addition, because the European Council often addresses major issues, sometimes its discussions precede work later duplicated by the Council. However, the decisions of the European Council remain political in nature and thus have few, if any, implications for the Court, unlike the legislation of the Council. 6. Economic and Social Committee The Economic and Social Committee (ESC) was established under the EEC and Euratom Treaties as a consultative body comprised of representatives of various social and economic interests.“ Currently, the ESC has 189 members” who are 233See Nugent, supra note 167, at 201-06. 23‘EEC Treaty supra note 1, art. 193. 86 nominated by Member State governments and formally appointed by the Council.236 Each member serves a four-year renewable term.237 The membership of the ESC is divided into three main groups, each reflected in the national groups and approximately equal in size.238 Group I--Employers includes members from industry, public enterprises, commercial ventures and financial institutions. The members of Group II--Workers are mostly drawn from national trade unions. Group III--Various Interests is associated with agriculture, small and medium-sized business, the professions, public agencies, local authorities and various public interest groups. Although the ESC members are appointed in a personal capacity rather than as representatives of an organization, their close association with certain interests inevitably results in a tendency to act as spokespersons for a particular cause.239 The ESC performs an advisory function within the 235The distribution of members among the Member States is as follows: Germany, France, Italy and the United Kingdom each have 24; Spain has 21; Belgium, Greece, the Netherlands and Portugal each have 12; Denmark and Ireland each have 9 and Luxembourg has 6. Id. art. 194. mm. art. 193. 237Id. art. 194. 238For a detailed discussion of the ESC groups and their membership, see Emil Kirchner & Konrad Schwaiger, The Role of Interest Groups in the European Community 60-84 (1981). 239See Nugent, supra note 167, at 211. 87 Community, issuing ESC Opinions and information reports on a variety of matters. Under the EEC and Euratom Treaties, ESC Opinions usually result from mandatory or optional consultation by the Council or Commission. However, the ESC also occasionally issues Opinions on its own initiative. The Opinions are drafted by one of nine sections of the ESC, which operate in this regard similarly to the committees of Parliament. The influence the ESC has on Community policy making is limited because the Council and Commission are not required to act on ESC Opinions. Mandatory consultation is restricted and ESC Opinions are often issued after key decision makers on the Council or Commission have already made up their minds. However, the ESC does provide a useful forum for the exchange of views from various social and economic interests. C. Other Actors in the Policy Making Processes 1. Standards Organizations Several European standards organizations have come to play significant roles in the telecommunication policy making process in the Community. The European Conference of Postal and Telecommunications Administrations (CEPT) was founded in 1959 and is comprised of representatives from the postal and telecommunications administrations in twenty-six 88 European countries, including the twelve Community Member States. The work of the CEPT primarily involves questions regarding service provision, technical standards and tariffs. In 1984, a framework for cooperation between the CEPT and the Community was established to help develop European-wide standards in telecommunications.“0 The Technical Recommendations Application Committee was created with the power to adopt mandatory European standards, or normes des Europeenes des telecommunications (NETs) in certain cases. In 1988, the CEPT created a new European Telecommunications Standards Institute (ETSI) to serve as a research facility, but ETSI was soon severed from the CEPT. The members of ETSI come from twenty-one of the CEPT countries and are predominantly manufacturers, although national telecommunication administrations, public network operators, users and service providers are also represented.”‘ 2“"See Council Recommendation of 12 November 1984 Concerning the Implementation of Harmonization in the Field of Telecommunications, 1984 0.J. (L 298) 49; Green Paper, supra note 19, at 108. 2“For a discussion of the CEPT and the creation and organization of the ETSI, see Frede Ask, Standards and the Role of ETSI, in European Communications 189 (David Shorrock ed., 1989). 89 Standards organizations such as the CEPT and the ETSI“2 are important actors in the telecommunications policy making processes in the Community. Such organizations have a large share of the responsibility for the development of telecommunications standards in Europe. Because their membership is comprised primarily of the national telecommunications administrations of the Member States and industry representatives, a great deal of the authority in the area of standards setting is not in the hands of the Community and its institutions. 2. Private Sector Participants Various non-governmental interests also play a part in the Community policy making processes. Among these are private and public companies, national and European interest groups and regional and local decision making bodies.“3 Because such interests are unable to directly approach the Council, they gain access to the policy making processes through the national governments of the Member States, the Commission, the Parliament and the ESC, each for different 2“The work of the CEPT and ETSI is supplemented by that of other organizations such as the European Committee on Standardization (CEN) , the European Committee for Electro- technical Standardization (CENELEC) and the International Telecommunications Union (ITU). 243See Nugent, supra note 167, at 226-31. 90 reasons.“‘ National governments are a prime target for attempting to influence Community policy. Specialized interest groups are often called upon by the Member State governments as a source of information for developing policy positions. Not only can private interests attempt to influence national positions on Community policy, they can also influence the way such policies are implemented on the national level. Thus, private interests consider it important to make their views on Community policy known at the national level.“5 Targeting the Commission is also important to private interests. The Commission makes itself accessible because it needs specialized information from private interests to perform its role as the main initiator of Community policy. Support from private interests for proposals from the Commission strengthens its position with the Council. Therefore, the Commission keeps an official register of several interest groups and the various DGs keep them informed of policy developments. Sometimes members of the groups become part of the various Member State delegations sent to work at the DGs.“‘ The Parliament and the ESC also provide such groups access to the policy making processes. Ministers of 2“See Kirchner & Schwaiger, supra note 239, at 37-59. 2“‘See Nugent supra note 167, at 232-33. 2"“See id. at 233-34. 91 Parliament and members of special advisory committees can be directly lobbied. In addition, approaching members of the ESC, whose main purpose is to serve as a forum for special interest representation, might be used as a means of influence. However, given the advisory position of the Parliament and the ESC in the policy making processes, they are not primary targets for lobbying. E. Policy Making Processes Policy making in the Community is complex, and involves different processes in which the actors interact in various ways. The main actors--the Community institutions, Member State governments and special interest groups--each differ in character and at times take on different roles, either active or passive, depending on the subject matter involved and the resources available. The subject matter can also determine the policy making process that is used because certain policy areas are more complex than others, occupy a more important position on the Community agenda or involve different balances of responsibility between the Community and the Member States. Since the ratification of the Single European Act in 1987, there have been two different policy making processes in the Community: the consultation procedure and the 92 cooperation procedure"7(Figure 4). The consultation procedure involves a single reading by the Council of a Commission proposal. The cooperation procedure includes two readings by the Council and, under certain circumstances qualified majority voting. A variety of legislative matters are decided by the cooperation procedure, including various matters of social policy” and most measures "which have as their object the establishment and functioning of the internal market."249 1. The Consultation Procedure The consultation procedure begins when one of the actors initiates the development of a policy proposal. Usually, this is done by the Commission.”0 However, other actors can require or influence the Commission to act. The Council can request the Commission to submit proposals regarding matters relevant to attaining Community 24“’Although the consultation procedure was already in place, the Single European Act introduced the cooperation procedure to improve the efficiency of decision.making in the Council and, presumably, to strengthen the role: of the Parliament in policy making. See Single European Act, supra note 12, art. 7. 248See, e.g., EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 7 (prohibitions of discrimination on the grounds of nationality). 249Id. art. 100a. 2"""See supra text accompanying notes 186-87. 93 COIBULIAILOI COOBIRATIOI PROCEDURE PROCEDURE Commission initiates a _ l proposal I EP gives an EP gives an Opinion Opinion Council issues Commission legislation takes a view on EP Opinion Council adopts a common position by qualified majority Within three months the SP: . J A I | l Approves Council Amends Council Rejects Council position or takes position by position by no view absolute majority absolute majority Council adopts Within one month Council may, act Commission reviews within three months, EP amendments and adopt by unanimity may revise Within three months the Council: I i l 1 Adopts Amends Adopts Fails Commission Commission EP amendments to act proposals by proposals by not accepted by qualified unanimity Commission by majority unanimity Proposal lapses but possible one-month extension if EP agrees Figure 4 Main Stages of the Policy Making Processes 94 objectives.”1 In addition, the various private sector participants might lobby the Commission to initiate proposals or exert influence internally through representation in one of the DGs.”2 The Parliament might also influence the Commission through a Parliamentary initiative report. The decision to issue a Commission proposal is usually made by the head of the relevant DG. Officials in the DG prepare an initial draft which is eventually sent to the staff of the Commissioner responsible for that particular policy portfolio. The staff might amend the proposal before submitting it to the Commissioner, who, upon approving the proposal, submits it to the entire Commission. Depending on how controversial the proposal is, the Commissioners might adopt it or hold a debate after which they accept it, reject it, amend it or refer it back to the DG for further consideration. During this pre-proposal stage the Commission might solicit various views from other Community officials, interest groups or researchers, depending on the nature of the proposal and the working habits of its drafters. A simple majority of votes is required to approve the 2”EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 152. The impetus for a request from the Council for a proposal from the Commission might come from the indirect influence of various private sector participants on a member of the Council or its staff. 2”See supra text accompanying note 247. 95 proposal. The proposal is then published, and the formal consultative procedure among other Community institutions begins. The Council receives a copy of the proposal and refers it to the Parliament and, if necessary, the ESC, for their Opinions. The various Parliamentary committees or ESC working groups then study the proposal. In the Parliament the proposal might be studied by as many as three committees, although one of them is designated as responsible for preparing a report for the plenary session. The final report usually includes amendments to the Commission proposal, if any; a draft legislative resolution; and explanatory statement; and annexes, if any, which might include reports from other committees. Once again the complexity and controversiality of the subject matter determines how quickly a committee report is adopted and recommended to the plenary session of the Parliament. Sometimes it is necessary to consult the ESC regarding a Commission proposal. ESC Opinions are drafted by one of the nine sections of the Committee, which eventually submits the Opinion at a plenary meeting. Once an ESC Opinion is approved by a majority, minority viewpoints have an cngportunity to be annexed to the ESC Opinion before it is submitted to the Council. ESC Opinions, however, usually have little influence over Community legislation because the Council or Commission might move ahead in the policy making process before the Opinion is issued. Although when an ESC 96 Opinion is issued, some note is taken of it. The Council usually does not wait until the Parliament and the ESC delivers its Opinions before beginning to examine the proposal.”3 Initially, a working party examines the proposal, discussing key points and determining the positions of the Member States. The working party eventually prepares a report noting points of agreement and disagreement and any reservations of the Member States. That report is then referred to the Coreper, which pays particular attention to resolving the areas of disagreement and reservation. When such issues cannot be resolved, depending on their difficulty and the disparity among the various positions, the Coreper refers the report back to the working party for further work or on to the Council for negotiation. Only the Council itself can formally adopt a proposal. A vote is not taken, however, as long as there is substantial disagreement among Council members. Even when a vote does occur, the number of votes required for adoption varies depending on the type of proposal involved. Unanimity is usually required to adopt policy in a new area or to modify or further develop an established policy 2”Even in cases in which consultation of the Parliament is required under the EEC Treaty, an Opinion of Parliament does not bind the Council in any way. See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 235. 97 frameworkaz“ .A unanimous vote is also required for the Council to amend a Commission proposal against the wishes of the Commission. A simple majority is required for procedural matters. Proposals for measures to establish the internal market’” require qualified majority voting.”6 A qualified majority is also required at the first stage of the cooperation procedure,”7 and, under special circumstances, the second stage.”8 Under qualified majority voting, the vote of each Member State is weighted, depending on its size. France, Germany, Italy and the UK have 10 votes each; Spain has 8; Belgium, Greece, the Netherlands and Portugal have 5; Denmark and Ireland have 3 and Luxembourg has 2.259 Fifty-four votes--which is 70 per cent of the total 76-- 2’"Because abstentions do not count as negative votes for Council decisions requiring unanimity, they do not impede adopting such decisions. See id. art. 148(3). 2”According to the EEC Treaty, " [t]he internal market shall comprise an area without internal frontiers in which the free movement of goods, persons, services and capital is ensured....” EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 8a. Article 8a was added to the EEC Treaty by the Single European Act, supra note 12, art. 13. 2”EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 100a. Article 100a was added to the EEC'Treaty by the Single European Act, supra note 12, art. 18. 2”See id. art. 149(2)(a). 2”Id. art. 149 (2)(e). 2”Id. art. 143(2). 98 constitute a qualified majorityu”” ‘Under this system, the five largest Member States alone cannot outvote the other seven, nor can two of the largest Member States block the adoption of a proposal. 2. The Cooperation Procedure The cooperation procedure is much more complicated than the consultation procedure. The procedure begins with a proposal making its way out of the Commission, being submitted to the Council and then being passed on to the Parliament or the ESC for an Opinion. When the Council receives the Opinion, the Council adopts a common position on the proposal,”51 rather than making a final decision as it would under the consultation procedure. Usually qualified majority voting is used to adopt a common position ,2” unless the Council chooses to amend the proposal against the wishes of the Commission, in which case unanimity is required.263 The Parliament then conducts its second reading. The common position, including the reasons which lead the z“Id . 2“Id. art. 149(2)(a), as amended by the Single European Act, supra note 12. mm. art. 149(2) (a). 2631d. art. 149(1). 99 Council to adopt it, is then sent to the Parliamentmz” The Parliament then has three months to take one of four courses of action. The Parliament can decide to approve the common position, in which case the Council adopts the proposal.“5 The Parliament can reject the common position by an absolute majority and send the matter back to the Council, which can adopt its common position by unanimity within three months.”56 The Parliament can amend the common position by an absolute majority and send the proposal back to the Council and the Commission.267 The Commission then has one month to review the Parliamentary amendments and decide whether to incorporate them into the proposal before referring it back to the Council.26$ If the Commission incorporates the Parliamentary amendments, the Council can approve them by a qualified majority.269 If the Commission does not incorporate the amendments, the Council can only approve them by a unanimous vote.”0 By voting unanimously the Council can also approve any Parliamentary amendments 26“Id. art. 149(2)(b). 2“51d. art. 149(2)(b). 266Id.. ”71d. art. 149(2)(c). 268Id. 149(2)(d). 2“91d. art. 149(e). ”01d . 100 not adopted by the Commissiondn‘ Should the Parliament fail to act during the three-month period, the Council can adopt the common position.272 Also, if the Council fails to act within three months after receiving the re-examined proposal from the Commission, the proposal lapses.273 3. Community Legislation After Adoption Once the Council votes to adopt a proposal, the next steps depend on the type of legislation that is issued. Regulations and decisions are binding without any further action.274 Directives, however, must be incorporated into national law by the individual Member States, which are usually required by the directives to inform the Commission of the measures taken.“ The way in which Member States incorporate directives into national law varies but usually involves adopting or amending administrative measures or legislation. Whether Community legislation is being properly applied at the national level is usually monitored by national authorities and agencies who communicate with 271Id. art. 149(d). mm. art. 149(2)(b). 273Id. art. 149(f). 274See supra Chapter III. 2753ee id.. 101 the Commission and the DGs.”° Two types of legislation in particular require followup provisions or measures: framework legislation and certain legislation intended to harmonize national laws under Article 100b of the EEC Treaty. Framework legislation lays down general principles and rules in a policy area but requires additional, more detailed legislation to cover specific areas within the policy framework. Article 100b legislation lays down essential requirements in an area of policy important to establishing the single market, particularly one in which standards are necessary, such as telecommunications. Under such legislation Member States are allowed to retain their national standards but agree to mutually recognize the national standards of other Member States. The national standards are eventually replaced with Community standards determined by European standards organizations such as the ETSI.277 Under special circumstances Member States are allowed to adopt national safeguard measures rather than implement ”61d . 2"See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 100b. Article 100b ‘was added by the Single European Act, supra note 12, art. 19. What constitutes the new approach is the agreement for mutual recognition of the standards of other Member States. Prior to enacting the Single European Act the Council would not adopt standards legislation until national specifications could be harmonized by Community institutions through the consultation procedure. Given the various problems associated with harmonizing national standards, the old approach was usually a lengthy process characterized by frequent delays and stalemates. 102 Community harmonization legislation adopted by qualified majority voting.27$ The special circumstances must fall under the non-economic conditions outlined in Article 36 of the EEC Treatym "or relat[e] to protection of the environment or working environment. . . . "230 Member States wanting to apply national safeguards must notify the Commission, which then confirms the safeguards after having verified that they are not a means of discrimination or trade restriction.281 E. Conclusion The policy making processes in the Community differ from those in other international organizations in several respects. Most obvious is that the character, composition and functions of the primary institutions of the Community are more governmental. In addition, many of the issues dealt with in the Community are matters of direct concern to the citizens and business entities of the Member States, 278See EEC Treaty, supra art. 100a(4). 279Such conditions include "grounds of public morality, public policy or public security; the protection of health and life of humans, animals or plants; the p[rotection of national treasures possessing artistic, historic or archaeological value; or the protection of industrial and commercial property.” EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 36. 280Id. art. 100a(4). 281Id. para. 2. 103 unlike the international political issues dealt with by traditional international organizations such as the United Nations.282 As such Community policy making is not so different from what occurs at the national level. For the Member States policy making is a process of resolving issues and problems in certain ways, either in national or Community forums. At both levels policy making is a political process of accommodation and compromise. Tensions and differences between competing interests must be smoothed over--usually through discussions, debates and deal making--in order to achieve overall policy goals. Difference do exist, however, between Community and national policy making processes and have been a source for criticism regarding the Community. Critics point out that the Community institutions are less directly accountable than their national counterparts to those who are affected by their decisions. In the traditional system of representative government, legislative authority is vested in an assembly of representatives chosen in a free election.283 The Community, however, is not wholly a 2“See John Fitzmaurice, European Community Decision- Making: The National Dimension, in Institutions and Policies of the European Community 1 (Juliet Lodge, ed. 1983). 283See John Pinder, The European Community, the Rule of Law and Representative Government: The Significance of Intergovernmental Conferences, 26 Gov't & Opposition 199, 204 (1991). 104 representative governmental system. Critics who point out the lack of accountability in the Community system often phrase their argument in terms of the democratic deficitmfl” The "democratic deficit" has been defined as the combination of the transfer of policy making powers to Community institutions and the exercise of those powers by institutions other than the Parliament, the only institution whose members are directly elected.”’ According to this argument the Commission--a grOup of non-elected civil servants--proposes policy to the Council-- a group of non-elected national ministers--which enacts binding, enforceable Community legislation that must be followed in the Member States despite any action by their national parliaments. Such critics equate the democratic deficit with a lack of accountability in Community policy making. The critics fail to clearly define "accountability," but seem to imply that a lack of accountability results from there being no connection between the Community policy making system and the people or national governments of the 2“"See J. H. H. Weiler, The Transformation of Europe, 100 Yale L.J. 2403, 2466-74 (1991); Williams, supra note 24, at 306-07. 2“See Vernon Bogdanor and Geoffrey Woodcock, The European Community and Sovereignty, 44 Parliamentary Affairs 481, 482- 83 (1991). 105 Community Member States.236 Such connections, however, clearly exist through the representation of national governments in Community institutions,287 the appointment of representatives to the Community and its institutions by directly elected national officials, the staffing of Community committees by the people themselves288 and the direct election of the Parliament. Various public and private interest groups and industry groups, many of which reflect the interests of various collectivities of the people, also have a say in Community policy making through representation in the ESC and standards organizations such as the ETSI and their lobbying efforts.239 Thus, to imply that the Community lacks accountability because it is disconnected from its members is incorrect. The alleged lack of accountability is also related to a 286Bogdanor and Woodcock note that public opinion polls and low voter turnout at Parliament elections might be signs of public alienation and hostility towards the Community. Id. at 481. 2”The members of the Council, the Coreper and the European Council all represent the national governments of the Member States. See supra pp. 63-65, 68, 84-85; Williams, supra note 24, at 302. 288Through a system Iknown as comitology hundreds of national civil servants sit on the various advisory committees, and.DGs under the control of the Commission.and on regulatory and management committees. See Williams, supra note 24, at 302. 289See supra pp. 88-91. PE} it; sy: fou fox| pat 1a th pc cr (1 106 perceived lack of formal legitimacy290 of the Community and its institutions. Formal legitimacy in institutions and systems, at least in the West, rests on a democratic foundation.“ The Community has established such a foundation through its Treaties which were ratified by the parliaments of the Member States. Therefore, it does not lack formal legitimacy. Questions regarding the accountability or legitimacy of the Community are really about the locus of control in the policy making processes. As evidenced in composition and character of Community institutions and other actors, the national governments of the Member States retain a large measure of control in the policy making processes. Their input is expected and received at every level, both behind the scenes and at the fronts”” Furthermore, national governments retain much control in implementing Community policy at the Member State level, particularly in the methods they choose to implement directives. 290Formal legitimacy implies that "all the requirements of the law are observed in the creation of the institution or system." Weiler, supra note 284, at 2468. Formal legitimacy should be distinguished from social legitimacy, which implies social acceptance of the system. Id.. 2"‘See T. Franck, The Power and Legitimacy of Nations (1991). 292For a discussion of the role of national policy makers in the Community policy making processes, see Helen Wallace, National Bulls in the Community China Shop: The Role of National Governments in Community Policy-Making, in Policy- Making in the European Community 33 (Wallace, Helen et al. eds., 1st ed., 1977). CHAPTER V TELECOMMUNICATIONS AND THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY ECONOMY Following the oil crisis of 1973 Europe's traditional industries--steel, textiles, shipbuilding and coal--were in a state of decline, and the European heads of state recognized the need for new sources of economic growth. In the Dublin Report, which was submitted in 1979, the Commission stated that a "considerable effort will have to be made for the Community, its citizens, its cumbersome social structures and its fragile political balances to react in a positive way by adapting to the new economic and political realities of the world today."293 .A key industry chosen to lead the Community to economic improvement was telecommunications, but for a variety of reasons that industry was also troubled during the 1970s. Substantial policy changes were therefore necessary before telecommunications could help revitalize the Community economy and further the goal of establishing a single internal market that could compete on a global basis. This chapter reviews the problems the industry faced during the 19708, the dual role telecommunications plays in the 293European Society Faced. with the Challenge of New Information Technologies, COM(79)650 final at 1 [hereinafter Dublin Report]. 108 109 Community economy and the policy goals the Community has developed for telecommunications. A. European Telecommunications in the 19705 By the end of the 19703 many industry watchers expressed concern at the declining position of the Community in telecommunications and related industries. The Nora and Minc report to the French government294 had increased awareness regarding the importance of telecommunications in the age of computerization, but until that time the European contribution to the field had been primarily intellectual. The United States and Japan were reaping all the commercial benefits. The inability of the Member States to compete in the field was the result of a variety of reasons having to do with regulatory regimes, business practices and the political climate.295 The main reason the Member States lagged behind the United States and Japan was the lack of cooperation at the European level. European telecommunications firms were operating in a fragmented, heterogeneous market, unable to produce equipment for mass consumption because technologies, 2“Simon Nora & Alain Minc, The Computerization of Society (1980). 2958ee Alain Dumont, Technology, Competitiveness and Cooperation in Europe, in The Technical Challenges and Opportunities of a United Europe 68, 69-70 (1990). 110 standards and procurement procedures differed from country to country. Therefore, firms did business almost exclusively in their home markets, which prevented them from taking advantage of economies of scale. The 19703 were also a time of technophobia in the Community. The environmentally-conscious Greens movement, which strongly opposed advances in nuclear power and biotechnology, put pressure on governments to resist technological buildup, a state of affairs that extended to telecommunications and related industries. There was also some resistance to technology within telecommunications firms. Managers in finance and marketing positions were promoted more quickly than those in R & D or manufacturing, making the former positions more attractive. Many other Europeans were also reluctant and cautious about technology, fearing loss of employment and invasions of privacy.296 Further aggravating the situation, European firms remained isolated from sources of innovation and investment during the 1970s. Few of them established connections with research universities to gain fresh ideas. There was also little contact with venture capitalists, who could provide the investment capital necessary to develop and support new projects. Chauvinistic industrial and procurement policies also contributed to the problem. Most Member States promoted a national champion in each industry, thus ”‘Id. at 69. 111 isolating a single firm from effective competition.297 Despite this protectionist approach to telecommunications in the 19703, the industry did experience some growth. However, given various problems in the regulatory regimes, business practices and the political climate, the Community was unable to take full advantage of the potential for telecommunications, perhaps because the dual role of telecommunications in the economy was not appreciated. B. The Dual Role of Telecommunications in the Economy Since the 19703 the use of digital electronics and the integration of computers with telecommunications has increased the potential applications of telecommunications for both residential and business use. These improvements have increased the utility and marketability of existing services and have created interest in new ways to handle information and enhance business productivity. The result is an increase in demand for telecommunications equipment and services. Thus, telecommunications has come to play a dual role in the economy. On the one hand it makes a direct contribution to the economy; on the other it has an indirect impact as an input into the production process of many industries. Understanding the relationship between ”’Id. at 69-70. 112 telecommunications and the Community economy is necessary to appreciate both its importance for establishing the single market and the telecommunications policy framework the Community has created to achieve that goal. A. The Direct Role The telecommunications industry in the Community has experienced a revolution since the 19703. The growth of the industry through network infrastructure and new service offerings has made its importance to the Community economy comparable to that of other large industrial sectors such as the aerospace and electric industries. This direct effect on the economies of the Member States is reflected in the increased penetration of telephone mainlines, increases in telecommunications revenues and investments and the overall contribution of the sector to GDP. In the period from 1978 to 1989, the number of telephone mainlines in Member States grew at an accelerated pace (Table 1). During that period the telephone became a mass consumption item rather than something restricted to business and emergency use. The total number of mainlines throughout the Community increased by 81% during the 11-year period. The increase in telephone penetration was coupled with 113 Table 1 Telephone Mainlines in the Com-unity--1978-1989l (0003) Countrv 1978 1983 1989 Belgium 2,178.00 2,843.06 3,747.91 Denmark 2,055.00 2,403.00 2,848.00 France 12,010.00 20,942.00 26,942.45 Germany FR 17,305.00 23,549.86 28,400.00 Greece 2,025.00 2,714.40 3,786.43 Ireland 412.00 613.46 903.00 Italy 11,456.00 15,601.03 21,265.52 Luxembourg 122.00 142.94 176.36 Netherlands 4,279.90 5,462.00 6,691.00 Portugal 904.28 1,248.91 2,035.10 Spain 6,185.00 8,456.71 11,797.16 Un' n o 15.173100 19.550.00 25.363.00 Total 74,104.28 103,527.37 133,955.93 Increase 1978-1989: 81% Source: OECD 1. Although Greece did not join the EC until 1981 and Spain and Portugal did not join until 1986, data for those Member States is included for the entire period for the sake of continuity. 114 an extension in the telephone network and an increase in new technologies and service offerings. Total investment in telecommunications throughout the Community increased by 39% from 1978 to 1989 (Table 2). New service offerings nearly doubled between 1975 and 1984 and are expected to at least double again by the year 2000.293 By 1989, total telecommunications revenues in the Community amounted to over US$88 billion (Table 3). This represented approximately 2% of the GDP in the Community. These overall increases in the telecommunications penetration, investment and revenues, however, can be misleading. On the one hand they represent efforts to catch up with the United States and Japan by bringing the Community into the information age. On the other hand, these efforts developed largely through a national, rather than Community-wide, focus. Most services and equipment were provided on a national basis under strict monopoly regimes. Therefore, technology changed slowly and was depreciated over long periods, usually 20 years or more. In a nationally fragmented environment protected from the operation of market forces, the costs of advancing telecommunications were higher than otherwise could have been achieved. In the short term the costs of ”non-Europe" ‘were higher prices for telephone introduction and the 298See Herbert Ungerer & Nicholas P. Costello, Telecommunications in Europe 21-22 (1988). 115 Table 2 Telecommunications Investment, 1978-1989 (1987 US$m adjusted for inflation and exchange rates)1 Countrv 1978 1983 1989 Belgium 552.77 580.70 593.48 Denmark 413.46 341.64 440.29 France 6,537.30 5,035.40 4,688.75 Germany FR 4,782.34 6,684.31 8,460.40 Greece 205.98 373.07 251.01 Ireland 165.35 313.91 200.55 Italy 4,202.08 4,237.86 6,708.80 Luxembourg 33.63 14.78 37.65 Netherlands 799.28 597.17 1,005.73 Portugal 125.05 224.12 546.74 Spain 1,832.59 1,626.75 3,839.17 United Kingdom 2,346.76 2,821.64 3,813.65 Total 21,996.59 22,851.35 30,586.22 Increase 1978-1989: 39% Source: OECD 1. Although Greece did not join the EC until 1981 and Spain and Portugal did not join until 1986, data for those Member States is included for the entire period for the sake of continuity. 116 Table 3 TOIOOOII‘HIAOCEAODI ROVOIIIIOI 19 89 Telecom 1989 Revenue per Telecom as COUNTRY Revenues Mainline 1989 percent of GDP (US$m) (US$m) Belgium 2,140.00 570.99 1.41 Denmark 1,946.24 683.37 1.85 France 16,316.14 605.59 1.72 Germany FR 19,906.76 700.94 1.66 Greece 992.35 262.08 1.84 Ireland 967.94 1,071.92 2.96 Italy 13,901.77 653.72 1.61 Luxembourg 120.40 682.69 1.82 Netherlands 3,969.83 593.31 1.76 Portugal‘ 940.52 452.15 2.03 Spain 6,122.85 519.01 1.63 United __Kingggm1. 220.819.97 1820.88 2.50 Total 88,144.77 635.55 1.70 Source: OECD 1.1988 Data. 117 delayed introduction of new services that often could be offered only on a national basis because of non-harmonized standards.299 In the longer term, however, the costs of ”non-Europe" were higher. The fragmented market structure of the Community made it difficult to achieve cost- efficiency and take advantage of the economies of scale a larger market could offer. Without a Community-wide initiative these problems could only become worse with the increased integration of computers with telecommunications, a situation characterized by rapid innovation, expanded service offerings, dynamic markets and aggressive international competition. B. The Indirect Role The shift to a more service-oriented economy and the advent of computer integration has led to wider applications of telecommunications in various industries. Of course, not all firms can add value through the use of telecommunications because some industries, such as banking, insurance, manufacturing and travel, are simply more telecommunications-intensive than others. However, as 299Fora detailed.discussion of the costs of non-Europe in the telecommunications sector, see Jurgen Muller, The Benefits of Completing the Internal Market for Telecommunication Equipmentcand Services in the Community (1988). 118 economies become more service oriented, the derived demand3°° for telecommunications in business should continue to increase. Thus, the use of telecommunications has an indirect but positive effect on the economy, adding value to firms by facilitating certain operations or processes, thus leading to improvements in information management and increased productivity and competitiveness.301 A primary use for telecommunications is for information management. Information is important in business because managers control businesses through the use and flow of information. Telecommunications technologies provide means to collect, store, retrieve and manipulate the information necessary for a firm to be competitive. The continuing globalization of production processes and markets has made the efficient management of information more vital. In addition, new concepts in manufacturing, such as flexibility and variability, make managing information more difficult and necessary. Terms of trading between firms can also improve through the timely flow of commercial information. Telecommunications technologies also help firms reduce costs by improving logistics. Better communication helps 300A derived demand is a demand for sources that are inputs for production processes. See Cristiano Antonelli, Information Technology and Derived Demand for frelecommunications Services in Manufacturing, 4 Information JEconomics and Policy 45 (1989/90). 3‘”See id.; Rob van Tulder & Gerd Junne, European Multinationals in Core Technologies 1-26 (1988) ; and Frederick Williams, The New Telecommunications 3-57 (1991) . 119 firms react more quickly to market developments, directing workers to where they are most needed. It also helps facilitate just-in-time delivery, thereby saving costs related to raw materials and reducing inventories. In addition, when information is easily accessible, questions can be answered and problems can be resolved more quickly, 3 thus allowing management to intervene directly to reduce costly slowdowns, interruptions or unwanted developments. Because one of the basic functions of telecommunications is to overcome distance, its use allows firms to save costs through decentralized operations. Satellite offices and plants and research and development centers can all be linked through networks. This allows firms to transmit information from one location to another rather than transporting goods or people, thus saving time and costs associated with shipping, commuting and energy. Any disadvantages related to decentralized operations can also be overcome with telecommunications, which allows firms to exert control from a distance. Problems related to time can also be overcome. Capacity within units of time can be extended through high- speed transmission. Networks allow the processing of information in real time, which allows several users simultaneous access to various data and network functions.3m Store-and-retrieve systems such as electronic 3mSee Nora & Minc, supra note 294, at 13, 174. 120 mail allow for operations in delayed time. Finally, the use of automated systems through telecommunications integration in manufacturing processes allows work to occur around the clock. These varied uses of telecommunications at the firm level improve information management and logistics and help overcome problems associated with distance and time. The resulting decreases in costs and increases in productivity improve the overall operations of firms by increasing the ratio of costs to returns, leading to greater profits and competitiveness. This leads to a positive albeit indirect effect on the economy through the use of telecommunications at the firm level. C. Conclusion Throughout the 19803 telecommunications and information technology had become increasingly important to the economic development of the Community. However, in order to take full advantage of the economic benefits offered by telecommunications and reduce the costs of non-Europe, changes in policy in the Member States were necessary. Divisive nationalistic approaches would only continue to fragment the market and isolate firms, thus weakening efforts by the Community to not only close the gap between it and the United States and Japan, but to achieve 121 Community-wide economic integration as well. Therefore, concerted action in telecommunications was necessary for the Community to meet both the external economic and technological challenge and the greater, though self- imposed, challenge of establishing a single market. The impetus to develop a Community-wide telecommunications policy was based on the rapid technological progress in information technologies, particularly by companies such as IBM.303 Although early policy making efforts primarily involved data processing, the essential issues addressed were the same: creating a homogeneous market through harmonizing standards and public procurement policiesu“” .After studying the recommendations made in the Dublin Report, the Commission issued a follow-up report?” one year later calling on the Council to develop a comprehensive strategy to meet the challenge of the new technologies. Drawing together the various policies developed in the 19703, the Commission proposed lines of action with three principle aims: 1) initiating measures to 303See Community Policy for Data-Processing, COM(75)467 final at 3; Eur. Parl. Doc. (No. 153) 26 (1974). 30‘For a discussion of the history of Community policy making in data processing, see Thomas J. Ramsey, Europe Respond's to the Challenge of the New Information Technologies: A Taleinformatics Strategy for the 19803, 14 Cornell Int'l L.J. 237 (1981). 30“See New Information Technologies: First Commission Report, COM(80) 513 final [hereinafter First Commission Report]. 122 facilitate the introduction of new technologies, 2) establishing a uniform Community market by encouraging common standards and 3) strengthening European industrial capacity in the field.""5 However, despite the consensus on the future importance of telecommunications, policy development moved slowly until 1983 when the Commission created the Task Force on Information Technology and Telecommunications. The framework of the approach to telecommunications policy was finally laid in the 1984 Community Action Program on telecommunications,” which the Commission drafted with the assistance of the Senior Officials Group on Telecommunications (SOG-T), a group of representatives from the Member States that advised the Commission on all aspects of telecommunications policy. In the action program the Commission identified four major handicaps inhibiting the development of telecommunications in the Community: - compartmentalized markets which stunt supply and demand; - the uncertainty of carriers and companies over what development strategies to put in hand; - weaknesses in the fundamental technologies of telecommunications; - backwardness of less favoured areas in respect of networks, equipment, and advanced 30“Id. at 3. 307See 1984 Community Action Program, supra note 15. 123 telecommunications services.308 The Commission requested that the Council approve the implementation of a Community program to overcome these handicaps.309 The Council acted quickly. Later that same year, on the basis of the recommendations of the Commission, the Council approved a program for (a) the creation of a Community market for telecommunications equipment and terminals...; (b) improving the development of advanced telecommunications services and networks...; (c) improved access for less favored regions of the Community...to the development of advanced services and networks; [and] (d) coordination of negotiating positions within the international organizations dealing with telecommunications....”° Thus, the way was paved for the goals for telecommunications to be translated into active policy. 30"Id. at 14. 309The Commission requested that the Council "approve the implementation of a Community programme, aimed at creating a consolidated European ‘telecommunications territory, which would giver both carriers and industry the benefits and added dimension of working on the Community-wide scale, and would put at users' disposal the services essential to promote competitiveness...." Id. at 20. 3”Minutes of the 979th meeting of the Council, 17 Dec. 1984. CHAPTER VI DEVELOPING TELECOMMUNICATION POLICY IN THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITY By approving the 1984 Community Action Program the Council set in motion a telecommunications policy program that soon accelerated.1033" Substantial progress was made between 1984 and 1987, during which time the Council took several actions. Then in June 1987, the Commission issued a Green Paper on telecommunications,312 which included ten proposed positions aimed at improving the infrastructure, services and competition in the sector. The Green Paper launched a Community-wide debate on the future regulatory regime for telecommunications and resulted in several new directives issued by Community institutions. This chapter reviews the major telecommunications legislation issued by the Community since the approval of the 1984 Community Action Program. 3"The policy work in the telecommunication sector was part of a more concentrated effort toward establishing the single market officially expressed in 1985, when Lord Cockfield, the Commissioner responsible for the internal market, presented the White Paper to the European Council, which was later implemented in part by the Single European Act" See supra notes 11-13 and accompanying texts One of the areas addressed in the White Paper is telecommunications, and the point is made that establishing a single internal market requires telecommunications networks with common standards at the Community level. 312See supra note 19. 124 125 A. Council ACtiOl‘lS November 1984-June 1987 Between November 1984 and June 1987, Community telecommunications policy development progressed rapidly. The Council issued nine recommendations, decisions regulations and directives in the areas it had approved from the 1984 Community Action Program (Figure 5). The legislation mainly concerns telecommunications standards, although the Council also addressed research and development programs and procurement contracts. 1. Telecommunications Standards Much of the Community action taken during the mid-19803 in the area of technical standards involved developing the framework of cooperation between the Community and various standards organizations, in particular the CEPT.313 131 November 1984, the Council issued a general recommendation addressed to the Member States asking that future new services be introduced on the basis of common, harmonized standards determined through the CEPT and other standards 313Although the CEPT had been working in the area of standards since 1959, the standards it adopted were not mandatory. As a result the Member States often adopted different standards, usually taking into consideration those of favored national industries and equipment suppliers. 126 Council Recommendation of 12 November 1984 concerning the Implementation of Harmonization in the Field of Telecommunications, 1984 0.J. (L 298) 49. Council Recommendation of 12 November 1984 concerning the First Phase of Opening Up Access to Public Telecommunications Contracts, 1984 0.J. (L 298) 51. Council Decision of 25 July 1985 on a Definition Phase for a Community Action in the Field of Telecommunications Technologies--R&D Programme in Advanced Communication Technologies for Europe (RACE), 1985 0.J. (L 210) 24. Council Directive of 24 July 1986 on the Initial Stage of the Mutual Recognition of Type Approval for Telecommunications Terminal Equipment, 1986 0.J. (L 217) 21. Council Regulation of 27 October 1986 Instituting a Community Programme for the Development of Certain Less- favored Regions of the Community by Improving Access to Advanced Telecommunications Services (STAR) Programme, 1986 0.J. (L 305) 1. Council Decision of 22 December 1986 on Standardization in the Field of Information Technology and Telecommunications, 1936 0.J. (L 36) 31. Council Recommendation of 22 December 1986 on the Coordinated Introduction of the Integrated Services Digital Network (ISDN) in the European Community, 1986 0.J. (L 382) 36. Council Recommendation of 25 June 1987 on the Coordinated Introduction of Public Pan-European Cellular Digital Land- based Mobile Communications in the Community, 1987 0.J. (L 196) 31. Council Directive of 25 June 1987 on the Frequency Bands to be Reserved for the Coordinated Introduction of Public Pan- European Cellular Digital Land-based Mobile Communications in the Community, 1987 0.J. (L 196) 85. Figure 5 Council Actions Taken November 1984-June 1987 127 organizations.314 The recommendation also requests that from 1986 onwards the telecommunications administrations (PTTs) take into account the recognized Community standards when ordering digital transmission and switching systems.”5 The purpose of the recommendation is to help establish common guidelines for the technological innovation necessary for creating a dynamic Community market for telecommunications equipment and harmonized telematic services."6 A program for work on common standards specifications (corresponding to normes Européenes de telecommunication (NET3)) by the CEPT and their mutual recognition is set forth in the Council directive issued in July 1986 regarding the initial stage for mutual recognition of type approval for telecommunications terminal equipment.”7 In: particular, that directive requires the Member States to ”implement the mutual recognition of the results of tests of 31‘Council Recommendation of 12 November 1984 concerning the Implementation of Harmonization in the Field of Telecommunications, 1984 0.J. (L 298) 49, para. 1-2 [hereinafter Harmonization Recommendation] . See supra pp. 87- 88. 315533 Harmonization Recommendation, supra note 314, para. 3 . 3“‘Id. Recitals. 317Council Directive of 24 July 1986 on the Initial Stage of the Mutual Recognition of Type Approval for Telecommunications Terminal Equipment, supra note 21. 128 conformity with common conformity specifications for mass- produced telecommunications terminal equipment. ”3“ The mutual recognition procedure requires the CEPT to draw up NETs and designate the testing laboratories, or other competent authorities, approved to issue conformity certificates verifying that terminal equipment conforms to the NETs. Such certificates must then be recognized throughout the Community, thereby foregoing the need to test equipment for type approval in each Member State in which it is marketed.319 Thus, the directive essentially explains in more detail part of the authority of the CEPT to determine Community technical standards. In a decision issued in December 1986, the Council recognized the need for common standards in the field of information technology--in particular computer systems components and software}20 The decision also covers functional specifications for services offered over the public networks for the exchange of information and data between information technology systems.321 The decision is intended to promote common standards developed by the 3“‘Id. art. 1. 319Id. art. 1 and art. 2, para. 16. 320Council Decision of 22 December 1986 on Standardization in the Field of Information Technology and Telecommunications, 1936 0.J. (L 36) 31. 321Id. art. 3 and 5. 129 standards organizations and as such, complements the directive on mutual recognition for type approval of terminal equipment.322 The Council also has issued recommendations in more specific areas, such as integrated services digital networks (ISDN)323 and cellular mobile communications.“ Each recommendation outlines a plan for the coordinated introduction of the technology into the Community and recommends that the Member States work within the CEPT to harmonize standards. In tandem with the recommendation regarding cellular mobile communications the Council issued a directive requiring the Member States to reserve certain frequency bands for cellular digital mobile communications.”5 322Thedecision specifically states that it does not cover the common technical specifications for terminal equipment that are covered in ‘the. directive 'regarding’ the :mutual recognition of type approval for terminal equipments .Id. art. 3. 33833 Council Recommendation of 22 December 1986 on the Coordinated Introduction of the Integrated Services Digital Network (ISDN) in the EuropeanLCommunity, 1986 0.J. (L 382) 36 [hereinafter ISDN Recommendation). 32“See Council Recommendation of 25 June 1987 on the Coordinated Introduction of Public Pan-European Cellular Digital Land-based Mobile Communications in the Community, 1987 0.J. (L 196) 81 [hereinafter Cellular Mobile Recommendation]. 32”See Council Directive of 25 June 1987 on the Frequency Bands to be Reserved for the Coordinated Introduction of Public Pan-European Cellular Digital Land-based Mobile Communications in the Community, 1987 0.J. (L 196) 85. 130 2. Research and Development Programs In addition to concentrating on standards harmonization, in the mid-19803 the Council also initiated several research and development programs dealing with telecommunications. In a decision issued in July 1985, the Council initiated the definition phase of the R & D Program in Advanced Communications Technologies for Europe (RACE) .32“ The definition phase of RACE was to consist of exploration projects in integrated broadband communicationstfl7 In addition, the Council issued a regulation initiating a Community program for developing improved access to advanced telecommunications services in the less-favored regions of the Community (STAR Program),328 in Greece, Ireland, Northern Ireland and Portugal. The objective of the STAR Program was to integrate those areas into the advanced telecommunications networks in the 326See Council Decision of 25 July 1985 on a Definition Phase for a Community Action in the Field of Telecommunications Technologies--R&D Programme in Advanced Communication Technologies for Europe (RACE), 1985 0.J. (L 210) 24; Ungerer & Costello, supra note 298, at 153-57. 327Id. art. 2. 328See Council Regulation of 27 October 1986 Instituting a Community Programme for the Development of Certain Less- favored Regions of the Community by Improving Access to Advanced Telecommunications Services (STAR) Programme, 1986 0.J. (L 305) 1; Ungerer & Costello, supra note 298, at 158-60. The STAR Program is funded through the European Regional Development Fund. 131 Community through investment projects.329 Both the RACE and the STAR programs are related to the framework program for research and technological development established under the Single European Act.33° Also part of the framework program are the second phase of the European Strategic Program for Research and Development in Information Technology (ESPRIT) and various programs regarding the applications of information technology, such as the pilot phase of the program in Advanced Informatics in Medicine in Europe (AIM) .3” Together these programs represent the legitimization of R 8 D within the Community system. 329Id. art. 1 and 2. 330The Council approved the budget for the framework program in July 1987. See Council Decision of 28 September 1987 Concerning the Framework Programme for Community Activities in the Field of Research and Technological Development, 1987 0.J. (L 302) 1. For a discussion of the various R 8 D projects involving telecommunications, see Ungerer 8 Costello, supra note 298, at 172-83. 331See Commission Proposal for a Regulation on Community Action in the Field of Information Technology and Telecommunications Applied to Health Care--Pilot Phase, cou(37)352 final. 132 3. Procurement Contracts In November 1984, the Council issued a recommendation regarding public telecommunications contracts.332 According to the recommendation Member State governments asked to ensure that their telecommunications administrations allow companies from other Member States to tender bids for various equipment contracts, including those for telematic terminals, switching and transmission equipment.333 B. The Green Paper on Telecommunications Despite the progress made regarding the 1984 Community Action Program, more wide-sweeping changes in the regulatory environment were necessary before the far-reaching effects of telecommunications would help the Community meet its established goals. To that end the Commission issued a Green Paper in June 1987 addressing the future regulatory environment of telecommunicationsfin‘ The Commission issued the Green Paper "to initiate a common thinking process regarding the fundamental adjustment of the institutional 332See Council Recommendation of 12 November 1984 concerning the First Phase of Opening Up Access to Public Telecommunications Contracts, 1984 0.J. (L 298) 51. 333Id. para. 2-3. 33‘See Green paper, supra note 19. 133 and regulatory conditions which the telecommunications sector now faces."”5 This process was conceived as a consultative one that would build on the consensus achieved in the 1984 Community Action Program.336 It would take into account the views of all parties concerned--Community institutions, PTTs and recognized private operating agencies, industry representatives, users, trade unions and other organizations with interests in the area--and identify common positions, analyze common objectives and examine the external problems posed by the world telecommunications market.” More than forty-five organizations would eventually participate in the process. The importance of the telecommunications sector to future Community development is reiterated at the beginning of the Green Paper.338 In general, the thrust of the Green Paper proposes increased competition in a Community-wide market in order to fully develop the potential of 3351d. at 10. 336Id. at 19. 3”Id.. 338The Commission stated that "a technically advanced, Europe-wide and low cost telecommunications network will provide an essential infrastructure for improving the competitiveness of the European economy, achieving the internal market and strengthening Community cohesion--which constitute priority Community goals reaffirmed in the Single European Act. Telecommunications have a great influence not only on services in general, such as financial services, transport and tourism, but also in trade in goods and on European industrial cooperation.” Id. at 9. 134 telecommunications. To that end the Commission identifies three tasks the Community must perform: 1) creating the necessary European scale and dimension in the sector; 2) avoiding the creation of new barriers within the Community during the adjustment of regulatory conditions; and 3) removing existing barriers in the course of the adjustment.339 These tasks involve restructuring the telecommunications sector in the Member States to take advantage of Community- wide economies of scale. In turn, the tasks are related to the general objectives the Commission implies throughout the Green Paper: 1) creating a common market in terminal equipment in order to ensure broad choices for users; 2) creating a common market in services to develop the infrastructure necessary to achieve the overriding objective of the 1992 market; and 3) creating a common market in network equipment to assure the Community's future position in information technology."0 These objectives involve the close relationship between the telecommunications sector and establishing the single market. The Commission sets out ten proposed positions regarding issues that the Commission believes must be resolved at the Community level for all Member States 3”Id. at 10-11. 3“"See id., Figure 13. 135 (Figure 6).’" The proposed positions deal with a number of areas, including safeguarding the ability of the telecommunications administrations (PTTs) to develop networks and services (Positions A and B), opening the market for services and terminal equipment (Positions C, D, E and F), creating the regulatory dynamics for an open market (Position G), fairness of competition (Positions H and I) and the external Community position in international telecommunications regulation (Position J). In the ten proposed positions the Commission tries to balance the responsibilities and needs of the PTTs with the requirements for developing competition in the sector and establishing the single market. After receiving comments on the Green Paper from concerned parties, in February 1988 the Commission further outlined its program of action for the progressive opening of the Community telecommunications market to competition."2 The Commission established priorities 3“Id. at 184. Issues to be dealt with at the national level are left for the Member States to decide individually. Such issues include the status of telecommunications administrations best suited for a developing competitive market, the method of financing the telecommunications administrations and their employment relations concerns. Id. 3”See Towards a Competitive Community-wide Telecommunications market in 1992--Implementing the Green Paper on the Development of the Common market for Telecommunications Services and equipment--State of Discussions and Proposals by the Commission, COM(88) 48. 136 Member State telecommunications administrations (PTTs) to continue to have exclusive rights to provide and operate the network infrastructure, with the possible exception of two-way satellite communication. PTTs to continue to have exclusive rights to provide certain basic services, especially voice telephony. Free and unrestricted provision of all other services, including value-added services, within and between the Member States. Strict requirements regarding standards for the network infrastructure and services provided by the PTTs to maintain or create Community-wide inter-operability, otherwise known as open network provision (ONP). Clear definition in directives of the general requirements imposed by PTTs on providers of competitive services for use of the network, including definitions regarding network infrastructure provision. Free and unrestricted provision of terminal equipment within and between Member States subject to type approval. Separation of the regulatory and operational activities of PTTs to avoid conflicts of interest. Strict review of commercial activities under Article 90 of the EEC Treaty and the competition rules. Strict review of private service providers in the newly liberalized sectors under the competition rules. Full application of the Community common commercial policy to telecommunications, particularly to build up a consistent Community position for GATT negotiations. Figure 6 Proposed Positions of the Green Paper 137 proposed positions in the Green Paper and announced a schedule of planned measures for their implementation.“3 On June 30, 1988, the Council issued a resolution announcing its support for the major policy objectives outlined by the Commission.“‘ C. Implementing the Green Paper 1. Competition in Terminal Equipment After outlining its policy program the Commission wasted little time before taking action. Even before the Council announced its approval of the program--which was not required--the Commission issued its directive on competition in the market for terminal equipment (Terminal Equipment Directive) .3“ The Commission issued the directive under Article 90(3) of the EEC Treaty, which requires the Commission to ensure the application of the competition rules and issue directives or decisions to the Member States whenever necessary.” France and other Member States 3”m . 3“See Council Resolution of 30 June 1988 on the Development of the Common Market for Telecommunication Services and Equipment up to 1992, 1988 0.J. (C 257) 1. 3“See Terminal Equipment Directive, supra note 21. 346See EEC Treaty, supra note 1, art. 90(3). The Court of Justice had already held that a public body such as a telecommunications administration was considered an undertaking engaged in commercial activity and therefore subject to the Community competition rules. See Case 41/83, 138 challenged the validity of the directive,” but the Court of Justice rejected their application for the most part, holding that the Commission had authority under Article 90(3) of the EEC Treaty to issue the directive.“8 The Terminal Equipment Directive is intended to correct the monopoly control Member States have extended beyond network infrastructure to the supply of user terminal equipment for connection to the network.349 The Commission believes that the extension of monopoly control to terminal equipment disadvantages suppliers of equipment from other Member States and restricts consumers from renting or purchasing cheaper equipment.”0 Because the Commission considers such control incompatible with the EEC Treaty, it issued the Terminal Equipment Directive to abolish such control and to introduce greater competition in the market in terminal equipment. The Commission seeks to accomplish Italy v. Commission, 2 C.M.L. Rep. 368 (1985) (British Telecom judgment). Article 90(3) does not require the Commission to consult other Community institutions before issuing a directive. 3"’See Case C-202/88, France v. Commission, Proceedings of the Court of Justice and the Court of First Instance of the European Communities, Mar. 11-22, 1991, No. 07-91, 5. 3“Id. However, the Court did declare the directive void in two respects: (1) in so far as it applied to special, but not exclusive, rights and (2) in so far as it applied to the termination of state contracts. Id.. 349See Terminal Equipment Directive, supra note 21, Recitals, para. 1. 3"‘oId. para. 5. 139 this goal, in part, by the following means: 1) 2) 3) 4) 5) 6) All exclusive rights granted by Member States to a public or private body for the importation, marketing, connection, bringing into service or maintenance of telecommunications terminal equipment are abolishedf“1 Economic operators must have the right to import, market, connect, bring into service or maintain terminal equipment;” Users must have access to new public network termination points, and the physical characteristics of such points must be published;353 A body independent of public or private telecommunications monopolies must have the responsibility for drawing up all technical specifications and type approval procedures for terminal equipment;”‘ Member State PTTs must allow customers to terminate, with maximum notice of one year, leasing or maintenance contracts which concern terminal equipment.”5 Member States must submit an annual report to the Commission regarding compliance with the Directive.”‘ The Terminal Equipment Directive implements proposed 3"Id. art. 2. The text of Article 2 also refers to special rights. However, the Court of Justice declared the Directive void for lack of reasoning in so far as it refers to special rights. See Case C-202/88, supra note 347. 3”Id. art. 2. 3”Id. art. 4. 3“Id. art. 6. 3”Id. art. 7. 3"“Id. art. 9. 140 positions from the Green Paper?” Before the Directive was issued, Member State PTTs had distorted the market for terminal equipment through their exercise of monopoly control. However, their assent to developing a more open, Community-wide terminal equipment market was evidenced in the Council resolution approving the Green Paper objectives.”a Therefore, although the Commission issued the Terminal Equipment Directive without having consulted other Community institutions, the Member States had had input into its development. 2. Competition in Services The Commission complemented its Terminal Equipment Directive by issuing a directive on competition in the market for telecommunications services in June 1990 (Services Directive) .359 Like the Terminal Equipment Directive, the Services Directive was issued under Article 90(3) of the EEC Treaty. The Services Directive opens up value-added services to competition immediately and basic data transmission beginning January 1, 1993. Telex, mobile 3”See Figure 6, supra, Position F and H. 3”See Council Resolution, supra note 344, para. 4. The Council Resolution was adopted by a Technical Council comprised of the telecommunications ministers of the Member States. 3”See Services Directive, supra note 22. 141 radiotelephony, paging and satellite services are excluded from the Services Directive.360 In addition, voice telephony is excluded on the grounds that opening it up to competition might threaten the financial stability of the PTTs . 3“ The Services Directive promotes the goal of opening up services to competition in the following ways: 1) Special and exclusive rights for providing services to the general public other than voice telephony are to be abolished;362 2) Technical interfaces providing information necessary to private operators must be published;363 3) All restrictions on the processing of signals before and after their transmission via the public network must be abolished;“‘ 4) A body independent of the PTTs must carry out the grant of operating licenses, the control of type approval and other regulatory activities ;”5 and 360Id. art. 1, para. 2. 361Id. Recitals, para. 18; art. 2. Under Article 90(2) of the EEC Treaty, "[u]ndertakings entrusted with the operation of services of general economic interest. or having' the character of a revenue-producing monopoly” may be excluded from the Community competition rules where their application would obstruct the performance of such undertakings. The Commission recognized this provision in noting that revenues from voice telephony provide substantial financial resources for the development of the network. Id. Preamble, para. 18. 362Id. art. 2. 363Id. art. 3. 3“‘Id. art. 6. 3“Id. art. 7. 142 5) Long-term contracts should be allowed to be terminated . 3“ Although the Services Directive has not been challenged, the judgment of the Court of Justice regarding the Terminal Equipment Directive” is relevant to the validity of the provisions regarding special rights and the termination of contracts. Like the Terminal Equipment Directive, the Services Directive implements policy positions the Commission proposed in the Green Paper.“58 Before the Services Directive was issued Member State PTTs had distorted the market for services through their exercise of monopoly control. A more competitive market in services was necessary to achieve the objective outlined in the Green Paper and establish the single market. At the same time public service obligations had to be respected, so the PTTs were allowed to retain their monopoly with respect to voice telephony. Although the Directive requires a separation of the regulatory and operational functions of the PTTs, such a separation may amount to more a matter of form than of substance. The same civil servants may still be deciding such matters, although under the name of a new organization. 366Id. art. 8. 36"’See supra notes 347-48 and accompanying text. 368See Figure 6, supra, Positions B, C, G and H. 143 3. Open Network Provision The Services Directive is tied to the adoption of the Open Network Provision Directive (ONP Directive) adopted by the Council on the same day:*” 'The ONP Directive is a framework directive concerning the ”harmonization of conditions for open and efficient access to and use of the public telecommunications networks. . . ."370 The conditions must be based on objective criteria and be transparent, published and non-discriminatory?” A Member State may limit access to one of its public networks or services only for reasons regarding the security of network operations, the maintenance of network integrity, the interoperability of services or the protection of data.372 As a framework directive the ONP Directive provides for the development of further rules and principles. ONP conditions are to be defined in stages373 from the following areas: leased lines, packet- and circuit-switched data services, ISDN, voice telephony, telex and mobile 369See ONP Directive, supra note 24. 370Id. art. 1. 371Id. art. 3, para. 1. 372Id. para. 2. 3”Id. art. 4. 144 services.374 The Commission may call upon the ETSI to draw up European standards as a basis for harmonized technical interfaces and service features related to ONP.”’ The ONP Directive established a framework for implementing one of the proposed positions in the Green paper.“5 Issued under Article 100a of the EEC Treaty, which requires the cooperation procedure, the ONP Directive is the work of several Community committees and institutions. In general the text of the ONP Directive follows the substance of the Commission proposalJ’" The Parliament prepared Opinions after both its readings378 and 37‘Id. Annex I. A timetable for the adoption of specific directives in these areas is set forth in Annex III. The Commission has already proposed a directive on the application of ONP to leased lines, including provisions regarding the disclosure of information with respect to leased lines and supply and usage conditions. See Proposal for a Council Directive on the Application of Open Network Provision to Leased Lines, COM(91)30 final. 37sSee ONP Directive, supra note 24, art. 4, para. 4(c) . ”‘See Figure 6, supra, Position D. ’"See Proposal for a Council Directive on the Establishment of the Internal Market for Telecommunications Services Through the Implementation of Open Network Provision (ONP), 1939 0.J. (c 39) 3. 378See Parliament Opinion on the Proposal for a Council Directive on the Establishment of the Internal Market for Telecommunications Services Through the Implementation of Open Network Provision (ONP), 1989 0.J. (C 158) 300; Parliament Opinion on the Proposal for a Council Directive on the Establishment of the Internal Market for Telecommunications Services Through the Implementation of Open Network Provision (ONP), 1990 0.J. (c 149) 1. 145 the ESC also prepared an Opinion.379 However, the text of the ONP Directive reveals that Council changed little from the Commission proposal. Those changes that were made are changes in of form rather than substance.380 4. Radio Paging : In October 1990, the Council issued a directive following the cooperation procedure, which designated the frequencies to be reserved for pan-European land-based public radio paging service (Radio Paging Directive).381 Issued under Article 100a of the EEC Treaty, the Radio Paging Directive is designed to allow the effective introduction of the European Radio Messaging System, an advanced radio paging system specified by the ETSI.382 The Parliament and the ESC approved the proposal by the Commission for the Directive, which simply lists the ”’See Economic and Social Committee, Opinion on the Proposal for a Council Directive on the Establishment of the Internal Market for Telecommunications Services Through the Implementation of Open Network Provision (ONP), 1989 0.J. (C 159) 37. 380Such changes by the Council are not uncommon and include renumber or reorganizing the articles in the Commission proposal. 381See Council Directive of 9 October 1990 on the Frequency Bands Designated for the Coordinated Introduction of Pan-European Land-Based Public Radio Paging in the Community, 1990 0.J. (L 310) 28. 382Id. Recitals. 146 frequencies to be reserved.383 5. Full Mutual Recognition of Terminal Equipment Given that the terminal equipment sector is so vital a part of the telecommunications industry, the Community - am IP‘LL a institutions have paid particular attention to it in the directives that implement the objectives of the Green Paper. In April 1991, the Council issued a directive on full mutual g recognition of terminal equipment (Full Mutual Recognition A Directive) .3“ As of November 1992, the Full Mutual Recognition Directive repeals the directive issued in July 1986 which introduced limited mutual recognition of type approval for mass-produced telecommunications terminal equipment.” Full mutual recognition will enable manufacturers of terminal equipment to go through a single equipment approval procedure common to all twelve Member States which is conducted by a laboratory or certification body on a Community list.386 The Full Mutual Recognition Directive applies to 383Id. art. 1-4. 384See Full Mutual Recognition Directive, supra note 21. 3“See supra Chapter V. 3“See Full Mutual Recognition Directive, supra note 21, art. 2-3. Under the old system of mutual recognition for type approval, a manufacturer wanting to market equipment various Member States was required to go through a separate body in each Member State. 147 terminal equipment intended to be connected to the termination of a public telecommunications network or to interwork with a public telecommunications network.” The connection may be by wire, radio, optical or other electromagnetic system.388 Member States are prohibited under the Directive from restricting the free circulation and use of terminal equipment that complies with the provisions of the Directive.389 Of particular importance are the essential requirements that terminal equipment must satisfy: 1) user safety; 2) safety of employees of public telecommunications operators; 3) electromagnetic compatibility; 4) protection of the public telecommunications network from harm; 5) effective use of the radio frequency spectrum; 6) interworking of terminal equipment with public telecommunications network equipment; and 7) interworking of terminal equipment via the public telecommunications network equipment . 39° Member States must presume compliance with the essential requirements regarding safety with respect to terminal 3”Id. art. 1, para. 2. 3‘““Id . . 3891a . art 0 5 0 3”Id. art. 4. F1 148 equipment which is in conformity with the national standards implementing the relevant harmonized standards determined by standards organizations.391 Manufacturers may subject their terminal equipment to either a type examination or a declaration of conformity.392 Like the other directives, the Full Mutual Recognition Directive implements a proposed position from the Green paper.393 The Full Mutual Recognition Directive was issued under Article 100a of the EEC Treaty, which requires the cooperation procedure. After the Commission issued its proposal for a directive,“ on its second reading the Parliament proposed amendments to the common position of the Council .395 However, those amendments amounted to changes in form rather than substance. In its final draft of the Directive the Council did not include any of the amendments suggested by the Parliament. The ESC approved the proposal 391Id. art. 6, para. 1. 392Id. art. 9-12. 393See Figure 6, supra, Position F. The history of the involvement of the Member States in policy making in the area of mutual recognition of telecommunication terminal equipment pre-dates the 1984 Community Action Program. 39‘See Proposal for a Council Directive on the Approximation of the Laws of the Member States Concerning Telecommunications Terminal Equipment, Including the Mutual Recognition of Their Conformity, 1989 0.J. (C 211) 12. 3"SSee Decision on the Common Position Established by the Council with a View to the Adoption of a Directive on the Approximation of the Laws of the Member States Concerning Telecommunications Terminal Equipment, Including the Mutual Recognition of Their Conformity, 1991 0.J. (C 19) 88. 149 without suggesting any amendments.”° 6. Digital European Cordless Communications In June 1991, the Council issued a directive, following the cooperation procedure, which designated the frequencies to be reserved for Digital European Cordless Communications (DECT Directive)5”’ Issued under Article 100a of the EEC Treaty, the DECT Directive is intended to allow the coordinated introduction of the European cordless telephone system developed by the ETSI.“ Like the Radio Paging Directive, the DECT Directive is technical in nature and the proposal of the Commission was approved by the Parliament and the ESC before the Council issued the Directive. 396See Economic and Social Committee Opinion on the Proposal for a Council Directive on the Approximation of the Laws of the Member States Concerning Telecommunications Terminal Equipment, Including the.Mutual Recognition of Their Conformity, 1939 0.J. (c 329) 1. 39"’See Council Directive on the Frequency Band to be Designated for the Coordinated Introduction of Digital European Cordless Telecommunications (DECT) into the Community, 1991 0.J. (L 144) 45. 398Id. Recitals. .u 1._.__—' 150 D. Conclusion Community policy development in the telecommunications sector has been considered a success story399 and reflects the importance of the sector in achieving the goal of establishing the internal market. Opening up national markets in terminal equipment and services to competition, liberalizing procurement by the Member State PTTs and harmonizing standards procedures should all help increase demand for products and services. Although changes in 3 technology and the global market have spurred the need for changes in telecommunications regulatory regimes, the Community policy making system has been responsible for the work necessary to surmount barriers to more fully realizing the potential of telecommunications in the Community. Since June 1987, all of the policy positions proposed in the Green Paper have been enacted, either directly or indirectly, at the Community level through the Terminal Equipment Directive, the Services Directive, the ONP Directive and the Full Mutual Recognition Directive. Such swift enactment through processes that are often slow is evidence of the assent of the Member States to the goals and ideals expressed in those positions. Behind that assent, however, is control. The Member States have retained a good 399See Economist Intelligence Unit, Special Internal Market Report: Telecommunications, 4 European Trends 14 (1991). 151 measure of control in determining Community telecommunications policy. Although their input is not always obvious on the face of the Community documents and legislation, it is inherent in the policy making processes at all levels, from the pre-proposal stages in the working committees and D63 to the final stages of implementation at the national levels.“” Evidence of Member State control in Community policy making is most apparent in the final stage: implementing the directives at the national level. The language of the recent telecommunications directives i3 imprecise but makes clear the policy goals to be achieved. Those directives that require implementation through national measures401 clearly give the Member States that authority rather than delegate any rule-making authority to the Commission.‘02 Critics of the directives note that change in the telecommunications regulatory regimes at the national level will not come easily, especially given the stake the PTTs ‘mSee supra, Chapter IV. ‘mOnly the ONP Directive and the Full Mutual Recognition Directive require specific measures for implementation at the national level. The two directives issued by the Commission, the Terminal Equipment Directive and the Services Directive, require the Member States and their PTTs to ensure fair business practices in opening up the markets to competition. ‘mSee ONP Directive, supra note 24, art. 11; Full Mutual Recognition Directive, supra note 21, art. 17. 152 have in their national markets.‘03 Thus, there is the potential for the Member States to exert ultimate control by interpreting the imprecise language of the directives to the benefit of their national telephone monopolies. “See Linda Bernier, Political Compromise May Tangle Europe Telecom Deregulation, Electronic Business, Apr. 16, 1991, at 70. CHAPTER VII CONCLUSION The unique qualities of the European Community (Community) are apparent in its legal order and institutions, but at its heart the Community remains international, an organization of twelve different nation- states. Although over time the Community has changed, growing in size and enlarging its scope, its basis has always been its Member States, without which there would be no Community. As the Community continues its path toward establishing a single market, it continues to evolve from its inception as a customs union to becoming a complete common market. It engages in this process by working as a confederation in which Community policy is determined as a collective but implemented on the national level, in most cases, individually. Although under the Community legal order Community law has direct effect and supremacy over national law, the Member States still retain a good measure of control within that legal order. The Member States are not only actively involved in the policy making processes that determine what becomes Community law, but also in specifically implementing and enforcing Community law at 153 home. The Community has recognized the importance of the telecommunications sector to its economic improvement and future goals. Through a series of recent action programs, research and development programs and, most importantly, legislation the Community has taken affirmative steps to translate Community goals into Community policy. However, the effectiveness of that policy remains to be seen as the Member States endeavor to implement it on the national level and change business practices that have become habitual and entrenched over the years. It is at this final stage of telecommunications policy making that the Member States may exert the most control in order to protect their PTTs and national suppliers. Telecommunications policy making in the Community is by no means at an end and can provide sources for additional research. Many more telecommunications directives are on the way, particularly in the area of ONP. The specific ways in which the Member States implement existing and future directives can provide sources of both qualitative and quantitative evidence regarding national control in the telecommunications sector, especially where differences in national implementation arise. In addition, future developments in technology and in the political structure of the Community might result in changes in the dynamics and structure of the current policy making processes. Thus, the 154 control Member States currently enjoy in the Community policy making might change with the Community. 155 BIBLIOGRAPHY »9 _ Lg.” BIBLIOGRAPHY Antonelli, Cristiano. "Information Technology and Derived Demand for Telecommunications Services in Manufacturing- " WM. 4 (1939/90), 45-55. Ask, Frede. ”Standards and the Role of ETSI." W W Edited by David Shorrock. London: Blenheim Online Publications, 1989. Balassa, Bela. Homewood, IL: R. D. Irwin, 1962. Bardi, Luciano and Pasquino, Gianfranco. "The Institutionalization Process Under the Draft Treaty." An_Eygz_glg§ez_yninni Edited by Roland Bieber, Jean- Paul Jacqué 8 Joseph H. H. Weiler. Luxembourg: Office for the Official Publications of the European Communities, 1985. Beloff, Max. "International Integration and. the lModern state." W333. 2 (April 1963), 52-62. Bennett, Walter Hartwell. Anegican Ineggies of Faderalisn. University: University of Alabama Press, 1964. Bernhardt, Rudolf; "The Sources of Community' Law: The "Constitution" of the Community." ' t Qommuniny gw. Luxembourg: Office for the Official Publications of the European Communities, 1983. Bernier, Linda. "Political Compromise May Tangle Europe Telecom Deregulation." Eiegtrgnic gusiness, April 16, 1991, 70. Bieber, Roland. "The Institutions and Decision-making Procedure in the Draft Treaty Establishing the European Union." An_Eyg:_gigsg;_gnignn Edited by Roland Emma; Jean-Paul Jacqué and Joseph H. H. Weiler. Luxembourg: Office for the Official Publications of the European Communities, 1985. 156 Bogdanor, Vernon and Woodcock, Geoffrey. "The European Community and Sovereignty." Parliamentarx_3ffairsi 44 (October 1991) 431-492. Bozeman, Adda. E9liti2a__and__sulture__in__intsrnational nifitgzyn Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960. Bulmer, Simon and Paterson, William- Ine Feggznl ngubiig 9f 9ermanY_and_ths_Euronsan_§ommunitxi London: Allen & Unwin, 1937. Bulmer, Simon and Wessels, Wolgang. Thg_jg;gngnn_§gnngii; .ns2isi2n:making___in___Eurouean___£olitissi London: Macmillan, 1987. Calhoun. John C-- Ihe_Eorks_of_lohn_§1_§alhouni Edited by R. K. Cralle. New York: D. Appleton, 1968. Commission of the European Communities. C mm'ss Dizgctive of 28 June i990 9n Conngnition in tng Markets o eco u e ' e Official Journal of the European Communities, 1990 (L 192) 10. Commission of the European Communities . annigsign eat“ 6 Ma 988 o Com etit o ' Marke o ' ' ' a u' e Official Journal of the European Communities, 1988 (L 131) 73. Commission of the European Communities. u ' ' fr C mmission t e unc' eleco unicat o o ress R rt 'n ' Work Done 'n h -ct'o cou(34)277 fin.1.' Commission of the European Communities. g_o_np_l_et_i_ng_tng ! ‘ -. 9-V.‘_. I! ' '2' _°I_I. !‘ °I_I.-I.I_°S"-1_ O 1‘ 32:22:33.9223211. COM(85)310 final- Commission of the European Communities. annission Engngsal igr n Regnlation on Connunity Actign in gng Eigig of Oath. .0 e h10__°' ec-uu ' -t.0 S is. ie t__O_ Healnn gnzg- -£iig§ Enasg, COM(87)352 final. Commission of the European Communities. 0 u ' ic for_nata:2ross§sinsi COM(75)467 final- Commission of the European Communities. W e w h n e of New Infognatign Technological COM(79)650 final- 157 Commission of the European Communities. W W COM(80) 513 final. Commission of the European Communities. W ounc_ I' -ct - ., ‘ ' ..-, - .- ,“ 1.077 ._ O I 2roxision_to_hsa§sd_hinssi COM(91)30 final- Commission of the European Communities. ect ve ro ' of t aws o em e t Concernin Telecommun' t'o 3 Terminal Eguipment, Including tng nutunl Becognitign 2; W Official Journal of the European Communities, 1989 (C 211) 12. Commission of the European Communities. W gouncil Digegniye on the Esnanlisnngng g; tne Internnl ungkgt fig; Ielgcgnnnnigntions Services Througn tng Im2lsmsntati2n__IuL__Qnsn__JEaaundt__£roxi§iCML__iQflzli Official Journal of the European Communities, 1989 (C 39) 3. Commission of the European Communities. Bnlg§_nf_£;ggggnze 91W Official Journal of the European Communities, 1975 (L 199) 43. Commission of the European Communities. mag—a m et 'v Comm t - 'de eco 'c t a e ' lg92--Implementing the Green Paper on the Development _§ tne Connon market {or Teleconnunicanions Services nnd eguipment--§§n§§ g: Diggnggigns nnd Ezgpgsalg ny ths_gonni§sioni COM(88) 48- Council of the European Communities. Wing—tn; Election 9f Represgnngnivgg gt in; Asggnnly by Qizect Univgzsnl gnffgnge, Official Journal of the European Communities, 1976 (L 278) 1 and 5. Council of the European Communities. Council Qecision of 28 Sgptembe; l287 Concerning tng Framework Programme for; ommun t ct'v'ties i 'eld esearc Technolggignl Develgnngng, Official Journal of the European Communities, 1987 (L 302) 1. Council of the European Communities. anngil_2ggi§ign_gf_zz Qgcembg; 12§§ 9n Standardizatign in the Field of Information Tgchnglggy and Telecgnnnnigntions. Official Journal of the European Communities, 1986 (L 36) 31. 158 Council of the European Communities. Qpnngil_2ggi§inn_gfi_2§ 9 a e ’ti as fo a Co u it ct' ' ' d eleco u ications. echnolo es--R e in vanced Co u ' at'o e no ° o Enpgp§__lgngfill Official Journal of the European Communities, 1985 (L 210) 24. Council of the European Communities. Coungil Qinegpivg pf 22 Appil 1991 on the Approximation of the Laws of the emb t tes Concernin elecommunica ions Term' a ui ment Inc udin the utu Reco n'tio o ir anformipy, Official Journal of the European Communities, 1991 (L 128) 1. Council of the European Communities. ggnngil_gi;§gpiyg_gf_ 2g 9 on t e n’ 'a St the utua eco nition of T e rov 0 e1 C 'cat n3 Iggninnl_fignipn§npy Official Journal of the European Communities, 1986 (L 217) 21. Council of the European Communities. Coungil Dipgctiyg of 22 ane 1990 on the Establishment of the Internnl gang: {gr Telegommunications Sepvices Through the t tw v 3 Official Journal of the European Communities, 1990 (L 192) 1. Council of the European Communities. ggnngil_nipggpiyg_gf_2 e on the e ue c t be Desi nated tn; ngpdinated lntpggncpign of Digital Eupopenn d ess Teleco unicat’ons ECT into the C mmuni Official Journal of the European Communities, Official Journal of the European Communities, 1991 (L 144) 45. Council of the European Communities. Council Dizggpivg gt 2; gnne 1287 on the Fregnency Bands to be Reserved for she Cpppginated Intpodnctign of Public Pan-European ellu ar Di 'tal Land-based Mo C u 'cati Lng_gpnnnnipyp Official Journal of the European Communities, 1987 (L 196) 85. Council of the European Communities. anngil_pi;ggpiyg_gf_2 Qgpober 1990 on the Fpegnengy Bands Designated for tng ordinated Introduc 'on o Pan-Eu o ean -Based Englio Rngig Enging in Eng gonnunity, Official Journal of the European Communities, 1990 (L 310) 28. Council of the European Communities. ggnngil_ggggnngngntign pf 25 June 1987 on the Coopdinated Introduction o: blic Pan-Euro ean Cellular i ita Land-based o 'le WWW Official Journal of the European Communities, 1987 (L 196) 81. 159 Council of the European Communities. ggnngil_gggpnngndntipn 8 C 'rst hase c ' c ' s anpzngpgy Official Journal of the European Communities, 1984 (L 298) 51. Council of the European Communities. c' co t g: 12 ngvembep l2§4 concerning pne Implementapign pf mo ' ' ' e ' o C mmunicati Official Journal of the European Communities, 1984 (L 293) 49. Council of the European Communities. anngil_3gggnngngnpign ecember 9 6 t e C o 'nat ntrod ct' pne lntegrnted Sepviceg Digipnl netwggk (lSDN) in tn; Enzgpgnn_§gnnnni§yl Official Journal of the European Communities, 1986 (L 382) 36. Council of the European Communities. gpnngil_gggnln§ipn_gf O t be st tu in Commu t ro ramme fo tne Development o: Certain Less-favored Regions of tne Communitv bv Inppgving Access to Advanggd Teleconnunicntigns Sgpvicgg (STAB) Ppggpanng. Official Journal of the European Communities, 1986 (L 305) 1. Council of the European Communities. anngil_gg§glnpipn_gf 9 n t e eve t t e Common Mar f9: Iglecommnnignpipn ngyiggg ang Egnipment np pg i222; Official Journal of the European Communities, 1988 (C 257) 1. Council of the European Communities. Qonngil Resolnnipn 0; Feb 8 ' ' na ' t e Qpnnnnipyl Official Journal of the European Communities, 1978 (63, 13 March) 36. Council of the European Communities. tes t 7 th nesting_of_ths_gounsili December 17. 1984- Council of the European Communities and Commission of the European Communities. Ingaty 9n Enpgpgnn Unign. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1992. Dumont, Alain. "Technology, Competitiveness and Cooperation in Europe." he e Ch en es a O u ' 'es MW Edited by Michael S. Steinberg. Savage, Maryland: Barnes 8 Noble Books, 1990. Easton. David- A_§2stens_Analysis_of_zolitisal_Lifei N e w York:John Wiley 8 Sons, Inc., 1965. 160 Economic and Social Committee. on ' e ve m on t e ws rne Member §tatss Concerning Telesonnunisatigns Ierninal Egnipment, Including rns nnrnsl Besognition of W Official Journal of the European Communities, 1989 (C 329) 1. Economic and Social Committee. ' o Counc' Direct ve he Establishment o t e Internal Marker for Teleconnunicstisns Ssryisss angngn e me ' 0 e wo P o '3' Official Journal of the European Communities, 1989 (C 159) 37. Economist Intelligence Unit. "Special Internal Market Report: Telecommunications." EEIQRQQD.II§BQ§1 No. 4 (1991) 14-13. El-Agraa, Ali M. . "General Introduction. " c s o e W Edited by Ali M. El-Agraa. 3rd edition. New York: St. Martin's Press (1990). Etzioni, Amitai. W128; New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc., 1965. European Communities. Treaty Establishing the European .Atomic Energy Community, March 25, 1957. Ireatiss Establishins__ths__Euronean__gommunitissi. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1987. European Communities. Treaty Establishing the European Coal and Steel Community, April 18, 1951. Irenties ab '3 e C ' 'e Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1987. European Communities. Treaty Establishing the European Economic Community, March 25, 1957. W tabli ' ' Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1987. European Communities. Treaty Establishing a Single Council and a Single Commission of the European Communities, April 8, 1965. eat“ 3 blish he o annnnirissr Luxembourg, Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1987. European Court of Justice. Commission v. Italy. Bspgrr_pr e t t f t a annnnirissr Case 39/72 (1973) 101. 161 European Court of Justice. Costa v. ENEL. Bspprr_gr_gssss Bsf2rs_ths_Q2urt_2f_Justise_9f_ths_fiuronean_ Qummnfiuasi Case 6/64 (1964) 535. European Court of Justice. France v. Commission. e o t ust' t t ' . Mar. 11- 22, 1991, NO. 07-91, Case C-202/88. European Court of Justice. Grad. Case 9/70 (1970) 325. European Court of Justice. Granaria. W B3I9I2_Ih2_QQnII_Qi_lB_Li§§_91_th§_EBIQEQQD_.99mmnfifi£§_ Case 18/72 (1972) 1163. European Court of Justice. Italy v. Commission. C 9 n n g n Market_Lau_Benorteri Case 41/83 (1985)- European Court of Justice. Les Verts v. Parliament. Bspgrp —-- 0, J 420‘ 0 1e _- 09".! QQmmfiDitigfil Case 294/83 (1970) 1357. European Court of Justice. NV Algemene Transport--en Expeditie Onderneming Van Gend en Loos v. Nederlandse administratie der belastingen. Bspgrr_gr_gnsss_fisrgrs the_Q2uIt_2fmIua_i2e_Qf_the.§urensan_gommunitiesi Case 26/62 (1963) 1. European Court of Justice. Politi. Bspgrr gr stes sergre ths_C9urt_9f_IustiCe_2f_the_Euronsan_Conmunitiese Case 43/71 (1971) 1039. European Court of Justice. Polydor Ltd. et al. v. Harlequin Record Shops Ltd et al. Bsporr sf Casss gsrore the Court_IuL_Iustise_3uL_fhe_JnuzuuuuL_Qommunitiesi Case 270/30. (1932) 329. European Court of Justice. Royer. Bspprr_gr_§ssss_fisrsrs the_Q9urt_2f_Iust1_e_2f_th__Eur_nsa__§omm_niti__l 'c e o n u ' 'es Case 43/75 (1976) 497. European Court of Justice. SACE. e t C ses o e t e u c e ommunit' Case 6/68 (1968) 409. European Court of Justice. Simenthal. e o ses 5929:: rns Conrr pf Jnstise of tbs: iEnrppssn QpnnnnirissrCase 106/77 (1978) 643. European Court of Justice. Zuckerfabrik Watenstadt GmbH v. 162 Council - Wis; of ths_Euronean_Connunitissi Case 6/68 (1968) 409- European Parliament- Dssisi2n__2n__the__Common__Eo§ition Estnblisned by rns Cpnncil with s View ts rne ngoptisn ' 'v ’ ' o e w em ates once nin Te co unications e in ° u ' ut a 0 ° ' T ' Conformity... Official Journal of the European Communities, 1991 (C 19) 88. European Parliament. MW s Qouncil Directive on ths Establishment gr pns ke e c u ' 'ons Se v' rns Inplementsrisn gr Qpen Netwgrk Provisign (932) , Official Journal of the European Communities, 1989 (C 153) 300. European Parliament. ' t Parl1amen__Q2inion_on_the_£ronosal_f2r s Council Directive on the Establishment of ths Internsl Market ror Teleconnunisstions Services Through eme t ' 0 w v Official Journal of the European Communities, 1990 (C 149) 1. Fitzmaurice, John. "European Community Decision-Making: The National Dimension." ’ ' ' EBIQPQQD.QQEEBDI§21 Edited by Juliet Lodge. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1983. Forsyth, Murray. M New York: Holmes 8 Meier, 1981. Franck. Thomas. The_22ser_and_LesitinaCx_of_uatignsi New York: Oxford University Press, 1991. Freeman, Chris. "Long Waves of Economic Development." Tns ° . Edited by Tom Forester. New York: Basil Blackwell, 1985. Friedrich, Carl .1.. "Federal. Constitutional. Theory' and Emergent Proposals. " ' ° a e Edited by Arthur W. Macmahon. New York: Doubleday, 1955. Friedrich. Carl J” W 2:32:1231 New York: Praeger, 1968. Gonzalez, Veronica, "Breaking Points and Visual Elements in Public Communications Campaigns." Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State University, 1992. 163 Haas, Ernst B.. "Technocracy, Pluralism and the New Europe.” £L.EEEL.EEIQD§Z;. Edited by Stephen R. Graubard. Boston: Houghton Miflin, 1964. Haas. Ernst B-- Ihe_nnitin9_of_Eur2231.2911tigali_zsonomis a c 9 -‘7 Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1958. Haggard, Stephan and Simmons, Beth A.. "Theories of International Regimes.” Internatienal_grsaniaation. 41 (Summer 1937) 491-517. Hay, Richard. e u o ssio t e ' t e ' Luxembourg: Office for the Official Publications of the European Communities, 1989. Hinsley, F. H. we 3 ° 1 ‘ r': - . ;- .t'.,; :- w--1 _ . -: Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1963. HitiriS. T-. Eur22ean__£onmunitx__fisonomissl New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1988. Hoffman. Stanley- WW 3_lnrignsr Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall,1960. IsaaC. 6.: DrCit.§2mmunautaire_§enerali 2nd edition. Paris: Masson, 1983. Jacobs, Francis and Corbett, Richard. e ean Enrlinnsnrr Boulder: Westview Press, 1990. Kapteyn, Paul Joan George and VerLoren van Themaat, P. trod ct' e w Eu ea Comm ' ' 3. Edited by Iaurence W. Gormely. 2nd edition. Deventer, the Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1989. Keohane. Robert. After_Begen2n2i_Cooperation_and_nisoord_in ' Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984. Keohane, Robert O. and Hoffman, Stanley. "Conclusions: Community Politics and Institutional Change." Tns ea t ' Edited by William Wallace. London: Pinter Publishers, 1990. Keohane, Robert and Nye, Joseph. Egysr sng Intsrdepengenss; E2rld.2211tiss_in_1ran§itioni Boston: Little Brown and Co., 1977. 164 Kirchner. Emil Joseph- 292W C2mm_nitx1___Ine___Coun2il___Erssidensx___and___Euronean 11 W New York: Manchester University Press, 1992. Kirchner, Emil and Schwaiger, Konrad. Tns_3gls_gr_Inrsrssr W Aldershot. Hampshire: Gower, 1981. Kondrat'ev, Nikolai Dmitrievich. Tns_Lgng_flnys_stls, trans. by Guy Daniels. New York: Richardson 8 Snyder, 1984. Krasner, Stephen. "Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening' Variables.” t' Edited by Stephen Krasner. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1983. Kunze. Renate. MW in der finngssrspnnlikr Stuttgart: Fischer Verlag, 1968. Laski, Harold J. "The Economic Foundations of Peace." Tns ' Edited by Leonard Woolf. London: V. Gallancz, Ltd., 1933. Levi, Lucio. ”Recent. Developments in JFederalist. Theory." 31W m Edited by Lucio Levi. Milan: Franco Angeli, 1990. Lindberg, Leon L.. "The European Community as a Political System: Notes Toward the Construction of a Model.” Wise. 5. (June 1967). 344- 337. Lindberg, Leon L.. "Integration as a Source of Stress on the European Community System." Inrsrnspignsl organization. 20 (Spring 1966). 233-265- Lindberg, Leon. L.. a 'c 0 an Inrsgrsripnr Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1963. Lindberg, Leon L.. "Political Integration as a Multidimensional Phenomenon IRequiring' Multivariate Measurement." Bsgipnnl_Inrsgrsripnr Edited by Leon L. Lindberg and Stuart A. Scheingold. Cmabridge: Harvard University Press, 1971. 165 Locksley, Gareth. "European Integration and the Information and Communications Technologies: The Double Transformation." S 1e o ea t g ' .t'o - , ‘_ Edited by Gareth LoCksley. London: Bellhaven Press, 1990. Lodge, Juliet. "EC iPolicymaking: Institutional Considerations." an Challsnse_of_the_ruturei Edited by Juliet Lodge- New York: St. Martin's Press, 1989. Louis. Jean-Victor. Ihe.ggmnunity_hesal_grderi Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1990. Ludlow, Peter. "The European Commission." Tns_nsy_finrgpssn ouuun ° IfC §,O-I.I_:. ° «.90. 1:. t 01:. 9a 0‘ Edited by Robert O. Keohane and Stanley Hoffman. Boulder: Westview Press, 1991. Macmahon, Arthur W.. "The Problems of Federalism: A Survey." ' Edited by Arthur W. Macmahon. New York: Doubleday, 1955. Merle, Marcel. "Federalism and France’s Problems with its Former Colonies, 1945-63.” W Edited by John D. Montgomery and Arthur Smithies. 1965. Mitrany, David. A flsrking Essgs Sysrsn, Chicago: Quadrangle, 1966. Muller, Jurgen. e e C n te nal for ecommu 'cat E i ment d Se v c 't Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1988. Nora, Simon and Minc, Alain. Tne Computerizsrisn pf figsisryl, Translated by Massachusetts Institute of Technology. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1980. Nugent, Neill. v e t 't'c ean Second edition . Durham: Duke University Press, 1991. Office for the Publications of the European Communities. Ihe_Court_2f_Iust12e_2f_the_Euroeean_Qommunity_ Luxembourg, Office for the Publications of the European Communities, 1986. Pentland, Charles. Inrsrnsrignsl Tneory ang Enrgpsan Inrsgrsrign. London: Faber and Faber Ltd., 1973. 166 Pinder, John. ”The European Community, the Rule of Law and Representative Government: The Significance of Intergovernmental Conferences." ggysrnnsnr___sng 90993111931 26 (Spring. 1991) 204- Puchala, Donald and Hopkins, Raymond. "International Regimes: Lessons from Inductive Analysis." Edited by Stephen Krasner. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1983. Ramsey, Thomas J.. "Europe Responds to the Challenge of the New Information Technologies: A Teleinformatics Strategy for the 19803." Cornell International Law Journal, 14, (Summer 1981) 237-285. Router. Paul. W 2nd edition. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 1970. Robbins. Lionel. 111W London: J . Cape, 1939. Schermers and Waelbrook- Iudi2ial_Erotestion_in_the_Euronean mining 4th edition. Deventer, The Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation Publishers, 1987. Schmitters, Peter. "Three Neofunctionalist Hypotheses." International_9rganizatiour 24 (Winter 1970). 161-166- Schumpeter, Joseph A. snsinsss nglss: A Tnepreticsl, . : - ca_ .12 _ — Ll: : - o 9- .9 t. 'st Erpssssr New York: McGraw Hill, 1964. Sewell, James P.. ' W ' 3. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1966. Ungerer, Herbert and Costello, Nicholas P.. IelsCommunisation§_in_Euronei Brussels: Commission of the European Communities, 1988. van Tulder. Rob and Junne. Gerd. Eurenean_nultinationals_in W Chichester: John Wiley 8 Sons, 1988. Vincent, Andrew. Tnssri es sf. rns Stsre. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987. 167 Wallace, Helen. "National Bulls in the Community China Shop: The Role of National Governments in Community Policy-Making." Enlisy-nsking in rns Enropsan W Edited by Helen Wallace, William Wallace and Carole Webb. lst edition. London: John Wiley 8 Sons, 1977. Wallace, William. "Europe as a Confederation: The Community and the Nation-State." Jou a o o k srngiss, 21 (September/December 1982), 57-68. Webb, Carole. "Introduction: Variations on a Theoretical Theme." WW Edited by Helen Wallace, William Wallace and Carole Webb. 1st edition. London: John Wiley 8 Sons, 1977. Weiler, Joseph, "Community, Member’ States and. European Integration: Is the Law Relevant?." gpnrnal of Cpnnon usrksr_§pngiss, 21 (September/December 1982), 39-56. Weiler, Joseph. "The Transformation of Europe." My isnrnslr 100 (1991) 2403-2483. Wheare, K. C.. £s§srsl_§gysrnnsnrr 4th edition. New York: Oxford University Press, 1964. Williams. Frederick. Was. New York: The Free Press, 1991. Williams, Shirley. "Sovereignty and Accountability in the European Community-" W. 61 (July- September, 1990) 299-317. Woolf, L. S. e ' e e . New York: Brentano's, 1913. 168 "7'11?liflllliflmflllfllr