..\.~.1p.: ....rqo.«ouaa.e 1;. v to. I. 2: tr: u! t 1 rue-(- :ustfviillloilivzlrrwrvn Stifrf-Ivvlvfllip .? 1.}. irrtvualrarvl av.rl. rl.lr o..A$..:€v . . ' ..:.....t.:. (.. .la::Vr. 1.. roll Itlvevo a: turf! a 5r. 4 C 2 1:4... a... v y vv.!-. 1 {rioov .(lra.t t. r Ilualll .u .c.-lvl,l..01lloll a... 1. r. ..xao(1:le 111.. l r.r.r t; . .t.?\..; V..: 1.9:... I. . n:.:..vr:ror: o......:c4 4:... :1, o. a." if! n’llFIIa (’7. it (I Irizuufflla I (5...!- !!(uoullrip .5. .u. 0!! 1- .V Clo r!!! 1. trrrvftv lu0¢.vll.ldtfl'!v:ll<. (tr .. a It. £11171); 1 21.6 1... I ...>x (I 1.!Il‘é 9.1;». Il.llluvl a1:!..’l tvlf. Elf:o..!¢av..v.!.avil;1€:.5! a) 1!!!! 1! Ir}... 1:: I'll.1:41:4(5)..srl2rlvl.vlvrnl I'Itllltlfirr. ruFfils Illl’ll’l‘lllllllllllll‘lllllllllllfill 3 1293 00791 7580 This is to certify that the dissertation entitled AN ASSESSMENT OF TAX POLICIES IN MODELS WITH ENDOGENOUS FINANCIAL BEHAVIOR presented by John Charles Navin has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph . D . degree in Economics Major professor Date [2 afibe” /9 9 2 M5 U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 LIBRARY Mlchlgan State I University 1—. PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. I DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE MSU is An Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution cmmux AN ASSESSMENT OF TAX POLICIES IN MODELS WITH ENDOGENOUS FINANCIAL BEHAVIOR BY John Charles Navin A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1992 ABSTRACT AN ASSESSMENT OF TAX POLICIES IN MODELS WITH ENDOGENOUS FINANCIAL BEHAVIOR BY John Charles Navin The purpose of my dissertation is to study the effects of corporate tax policies on the financial and investment decisions of firms in the U.S. economy. In the first section, I construct a model of firm investment and financial behavior which can be used to study the effects of various tanpolicies in a computational general equilibrium (CGE) model. In the second section, I use a panel data set of 781 firms to examine the impact of changes in statutory tax rates on firms' debt/capital ratios. Data on firms' debt/capital ratios were taken from the COMPUSTAT data tape, covering the years 1969-1988. A fixed-effects model was used to measure the impact of tax rate changes on firm's debt/capital ratios. The results of the empirical estimation indicate that the response of firms to changes in the tax rates was very small. The elasticity estimates, after correcting for autocorrelation, ranged. between -0.11 and -0.73 for' the debt/capital ratios with respect to changes in the personal income tax rate. In the final section, I use a nine-sector CGE model to examine the effects of three different tax policy proposals: full corporate tax integration, a reduction in the corporate income tax rate, and a dividend exclusion from the personal income tax. The model consists of nine production sectors, a single consumer, and also a government sector. The model incorporates the empirical elasticities of firm financial behavior, in.order to allow firms to adjust.their debt/capital ratios in response to changes in tax policy. The tax policy simulations resulted in welfare gains under each policy proposal. The welfare gains ranged between $463 billion, under full corporate tax integration, and $340 billion, for the reduction in the corporate income tax rate. This dissertation is dedicated to my brother, Jim. iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to thank all of the members of my committee, John Goddeeris, Larry Martin, Ron Fisher, and Charles Ballard, for all of their time and patience in seeing this work through to its completion. I would especially like to thank my advisor, Charley Ballard, for all of the long hours spent reading earlier drafts of my dissertation and for his unwavering support. My wife Lynn, as well as my parents provided phenomenal emotional as well as financial support. Without them I could have never gotten this far. I would especially like to say thank you to my dad, without his constant pep talks I would have given up long ago. Finally, I would like to thank all of my friends at Michigan State for all of their help, especially Kari Foreback, Marneta Griffin, Gil Davis, and Kel Utendorf. TABLE OF CONTENTS 1 INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . Overview of Some Corporate Income Tax Distortions . . . . . . . . . . . Review of the Literature . . . . . . . Corporate Tax Integraton and CGE Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . Theories of Corporate Financial Leverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 MODEL OF FIRM BEHAVIOR . . . . . . . 3 THE EFFECT OF PERSONAL AND CORPORATE TAXES ON FIRMS' DEBT/CAPITAL UUUMQ UNNNN 0.. UMP 3. NH hhbhéhfihfi \lO‘O‘O‘UIéwNH RATIOS . . . . . . . . . . . Empirical Implications of the Bankruptcy Models . Estimation . . . . Model . . . . . . Data . . . . . . . Results . . . . . Conclusions . . . 4 DESCRIPTION OF THE SIMULATION MODEL . . . . . . . . . . . . Introduction . . . . . . . . . The Consumer's Problem . . . . Producer's Problem . . . . . . The Government Sector . . . . General Solution to the Model Calibration . . . . . Production Sector . . Consumption Parameters Data . . . . . . . . . 5 SIMULATIONS . . . . . . . . Introduction . . . . . . . . . Full Integration Results . . . Reduction of the Corporate Tax Dividend Deduction . . . . . . Sensitivity Analysis . . . . . vi 39 39 4O 40 41 47 54 56 56 56 60 73 74 76 77 79 82 84 84 87 92 93 95 TABLE OF CONTENTS (cont'd) 5.5.1 Adjustment Costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96 5.5.2 Depreciation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97 5.5.3 Debt/Capital Elasticities . . . . . . . . . . 98 5.5.4 Classification of Corporate and Noncorporate Sectors . . . . . . . . . . . . 102 5.5.5 Required Consumption Ratio . . . . . . . . . . 104 5.6 Comparison with Other Studies . . . . . . . . 107 5.7 Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 REFERENCES 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 1 12 vii LIST OF TABLES TABLE 1- Summary of Features of Computational General Equilibrium Models . . . . . . . . . . TABLE 2- Listing of Corporate Sectors Used in Estimation O O I O O O O O O O O 0 TABLE 3- Summary of Debt/Capital Ratios by seCtor 1969-1988 e e o e o o o o o 0 TABLE 4- Initial Regression Results . . . . . . . TABLE 5- Average Autocorrelation Coefficients by Sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . TABLE 6- Regression Results After Correcting for Autocorrelation . . . . . . . . . . TABLE 7- Production Sectors Used in the Simulation MOdel O I O O O O O O O 0 TABLE 8- Breakdown of Capital Stock Classification by sector 0 O O O I O O O O O O O O 0 TABLE 9- Assets and Their Tax Parameters . . . . TABLE 10- Base-Case Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . TABLE 11- Summary of Initial Simulation Results . . viii 15 44 45 48 51 52 63 65 70 83 95 Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION 1.1. Introduction The corporate income tax may have long-term effects on savings, investment, and firm financial decisions. The purpose of my dissertation is to study the effects of corporate tax policies on the financial and investment decisions of firms in the U.S. economy. I begin with a brief survey of earlier work. I then construct a model which can be used to study the effects of various tax policies in a computational general equilibrium (CGE) model. The model yields implications for corporate debt/capital ratios that may be tested econometrically. In Chapter 3, I report on my investigation into the effects of changes in the personal and corporate tax rates on firms' financial decisions, using a panel data set of annual data from 1969 through 1988. Then in Chapter 4, I describe the CGE model and in Chapter 5, report on the results of the policy simulations. 1.2. Overview of Some Corporate Income Tax Distortions The corporate income ‘tax: is an important (although relatively’ declining) source of :revenue for the federal government, ranking third behind the payroll tax and the 2 1 It has been criticized on the grounds personal income tax. that it distorts individual and firm behavior.2 The following are some decisions which are believed to be distorted by the corporate income tax: (1) The firm's decision on whether to finance new capital with new issues of equity or new issues of debt. Under the current tax code, interest payments on debt are deductible from the corporate tax base, while disbursements to equity holders are not. This asymmetry in the tax code heavily favors debt finance. See, for example, Stiglitz (1973) or Gordon and Malkiel (1981). (2) The firm's decision on whether to undertake new investment. A key factor in determining whether to undertake new investment is the after-tax rate of return received by the firm. As the corporate income tax rate changes, the rate of return required on investments will fluctuate. This distortion has been discussed by Auerbach and Hassett (1989) , 1 According to Pechman (1987) the corporate income tax accounted for approximately 8 percent of federal revenues compared with 45 percent from the personal income tax and 37 percent from payroll taxes in 1986. Pechman points out that the percentage of total federal tax revenue raised by the corporate income tax has been declining steadily over the past 30 years, falling from 27.3% in 1955, to 8% in 1986. 2Although the percentage of total federal tax revenue received form the corporate income tax is declining, this does not necessarily imply that the size of the welfare losses incurred due to the existence of the corporate income tax are declining. In fact, it may imply that the size of the distortions caused per dollar of tax revenue raised may be increasing. 3 Feldstein and Frisch (1977), Fullerton and Henderson (1989), and Hall and Jorgenson (1967). (3) The allocation of capital between the corporate and noncorporate sectors. Different tax rates between sectors will cause capital to move out of the higher-tax sector into the lower-tax sector. The seminal work on this distortion was done by Harberger (1962, 1966), using a two-sector model. Harberger's most famous result is that a tax on capital in the corporate sector is borne by all owners of capital, even if their capital is not incorporated. Harberger also estimated the efficiency loss from the taxation of capital. He estimated that the deadweight loss from the taxation of capital between 1953 and 1959 was between 2.4 and 7.0 percent of corporate income tax revenue. The development of CGE techniques has allowed the construction of multiple-sector models. See, for example, ShoveniandHWhalley'(1972), Shoven (1976), and Fullerton, King, Shoven, and Whalley (1981).3 Gravelle and Kotlikoff (1989) have explored the misallocation of capital between corporate and noncorporate establishments which produce in the same sector. Their results indicate that, if one takes into account the presence of corporate and noncorporate capital in 3 Shoven (1976) has twelve production sectors in his model. In addition to disaggregation, Shoven also corrects a mathematical error by Harberger. Harberger understates the true amount of capital income in his model by almost four million dollars. Both the higher level of disaggregation and the correction of Harberger's error lead to welfare gains which were, on average, 40 percent larger than Harberger's results. 4 the same sector, the distortion is much larger than previously believed. They examine this distortion at a high level of industry aggregation. It may be the case that, if one were to take a more disaggregated view of the economy, this distortion may be much smaller than their results indicate. Another criticism is the accuracy of their model in capturing the decision on whether to incorporate. Their model provides a high elasticity of incorporation with respect to tax parameter changes within the model. Gordon and MacKie-Mason (1990) find that, empirically, there appears to be little elasticity in the decision to incorporate with respect to changes in the tax system. In any event, I choose to focus on the more traditional question of the misallocation of capital between the corporate and noncorporate sector. (4) The individual savings decision. If one accepts Harberger's result that the burden of the corporate tax is shifted to all owners of capital, then the corporate income tax lowers the after-tax rate of return for all savers. This biases their savings decision in favor of current consumption instead of future consumption. The effect of taxation on intertemporal decisions has been explored by a number of authors, including Atkinson (1971, 1980), Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987), Ballard (1990), Feldstein (1978), Feldstein and Frisch (1977), and Periera (1988). (5) The dividend payout policy of firms. Under the current tax structure, dividends are taxed twice, once as corporate income, and once as personal income. This increases 5 the cost to shareholders of receiving dividends, and biases the firm toward a low payout ratio. The effect of the tax system on corporate dividend policy is explored by Poterba and Summers (1985) and Feldstein and Green (1983). The simplest method for removing these distortions would be the elimination of the corporate income tax. The outright elimination of the corporate tax is unlikely for two major reasons. The first is that, despite its relative decline, the corporate income tax is a major source of federal revenue, raising approximately $83.9 billion in 1987.4 Secondly, the elimination of the corporate income tax also may lead to some distortions of its own. One such distortion would be the incentive for individuals to shelter income in corporations in order to avoid paying personal income taxes. Short of simple elimination of the corporate income tax, some economists have suggested the integration of the corporate and personal income taxes. One of the most thorough discussions of corporate tax integration is found in McLure (1979). He discusses the administrative implications of tax integration as well as various other proposals. The possible proposals for integration range from complete integration to partial dividend relief} 'Under the partnership method of full corporate integration, the corporate tax is eliminated and all corporate income is attributed to equity holders of the ‘ U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Statistical Absttact of the United States, Washington, D.C., January 1990, P. 274. 6 corporation, based on the number of shares held, and is taxed as personal income. Another proposal is to allow a deduction for dividends within the corporate tax. If firms choose to pay out all earnings as dividends, a 100% dividend deduction would have the same effect as full integration. However, even with a 100% deduction, this would probably not have as great an effect as full integration, because firms may have other reasons for retaining earnings. Dividend relief, within the personal income tax, reduces or eliminates the double taxation of dividends. One method would be to issue a credit to taxpayers for the corporate income tax jpaid on income disbursed. to shareholders as dividends. Besides full dividend relief, it is also possible to give individuals a partial dividend credit. Although this would not eliminate the double taxation of dividends, it would lessen the distortion. 1.3. Review of the Literature 1.3.1. gotpotate Tax Integration and CGE models This section briefly reviews earlier work on tax integration, and CGE modeling. Readers familiar with this literature may want to proceed to section [1.3.2.] A number of studies have examined the effect of various corporate tax integration plans. Using tax return data from 7 the U.S. Department of Treasury's Tax File of 1973, Feldstein and Frisch (1977) examine the distributional and revenue implications of full corporate integration and a revenue- neutral partial integration plan. They report that full corporate integration may result in annual welfare gains as large as $7 billion (approximately 19.25% of federal corporate income tax revenue in 1973) by reducing the distortion on the individual savings decision alone. Ballentine and McLure (1981) examine the effects of full integration of the personal and corporate tax systems, while taking into account the financial behavior of firms. They modify a two-sector Harberger general equilibrium model to incorporate a model of firm financial decision making. They find that, with the incorporation of the corporate financial structure, the implementation of corporate tax integration will lead to greater welfare gains to the economy, than in an otherwise identical two-sector model which abstracts from firm behavior. This is due to a reduction in the difference between the rate of return on corporate and noncorporate capital, and a reduction in the risk premiums required on corporate securities. The reduction in the risk premiums will lead to relatively larger increases in the income of investors in the noncorporate sector, because previously the corporate income tax burden was shifted onto owners of noncorporate 8 capital. This will also result in an increase in the progressivity of the income tax.5 These studies by Feldstein and Frisch and by Ballentine and McLure made important contributions to the examination of integration. However, these studies are lacking in that they are not able to model more completely the complexity of the tax laws and the ability of individuals to change their behavior in response to changes in these laws. Advances in computer technology have allowed researchers to use CGE models to'simulate the effects of changes in tanpolicy, using large- scale models of the United States economy. Computational models allow the modeling of multiple production sectors as well as many different types of consumers. These models also allow for a complex modeling of the current tax system. These models have also been used to study the effects of corporate tax integration. Fullerton, Shoven, King, and Whalley [FKSW (1981)] use a CGE model to examine the welfare effects of four corporate tax integration plans, ranging from full integration to partial dividend relief. Their model consists of 19 producing sectors which produce 16 different consumer goods. The model also includes 12 differing consumer classes, which are separated based on income levels. Their model's data set consists of information based on the 1973 tax rates, capital stocks, and income distribution. of the United States. 5 This result is based on the fact that the ownership of corporate capital tends to be more highly concentrated in the upper-income classes than the ownership of noncorporate capital. 9 However, FKSW do not explicitly model the effects of changes in the tax system on corporate financial behavior. The authors run simulations under revenue-neutral conditions, adjusting personal tax rates so that there is no loss in total tax revenue. The static gains from total integration are very large (on the order of $6 billion per year, approximately 16.5% of total federal corporate income tax revenue, in 1973 dollars). The plans for dividend relief resulted in efficiency gains of about half as much as the total integration plan. FKSW also look at dynamic gains, i.e., gains which accrue in the future due to increases in the accumulation of capital. These changes are very large, with a present value of at least $100 billion in every case. Fullerton (1983) examines the effects of full corporate tax integration in a model with partially mobile industry- specific capital. Fullerton uses the nineteen-sector FSKW model, but restricts the flow of capital out of some sectors to the amount of depreciation that occurs in that sector's capital stock. In his model, a large portion of the economy's capital stock is freely mobile. A portion of the capital stock is, however, restricted to be sector-specific. The sector-specific capital is assumed to remain in the original production sector. The sector-specific capital will depreciate away over the course of simulations, and after ten years, all capital is assumed to be perfectly mobile. In his most restrictive case, Fullerton assumes that five production sectors consist of sector-specific capital. Full integration lO simulations, under' his :most. restrictive case, result in dynamic welfare gains that are $5 billion dollars lower than those found by FSKW. Fullerton and Gordon (1983) also use a CGE model to examine the effects of changes in tax policy on the United States economy. They modify the FKSW model to incorporate the effects of changes in the tax system on the selection of corporate debt/capital ratios. The authors rely on the bankruptcy theory of corporate finance, which is discussed in Gordon and.Malkiel (1981). Under this theory, firms trade off the benefits of financing new investment with debt against the increased costs of bankruptcy associated with a greater amount of leverage. The theories of financial leverage will be discussed in greater detail in section [1.3.2]. Fullerton and Gordon examine the effects of full integration via the partnership method. Uhder full integration, there is no longer any tax advantage to using debt, so firms have an optimal debt/capital ratio of zero. In every revenue-neutral simulation in which personal tax rates were increased to compensate for lost revenue, full integration resulted in welfare losses. There were welfare gains when the loss in tax revenue was replaced by a lump-sum tax, but they were very small in comparison to those found by FKSW (1981). The changes in the FKSW model resulted in a dramatic change in the effects of corporate tax integration. Although the Fullerton-Gordon paper would seem to indicate that there are few benefits to corporate tax 11 integration, one must be cautious in evaluating their results. The reason for this caution is the type of risk that they incorporate into their model. In their model, Fullerton and Gordon focus on the income risk of firm ownership. The total return on a capital asset is composed of two parts. These are the current return on the asset and changes in the value of that asset. Income risk is associated with changes in the current return.to the asset» Fullerton and.Gordon assume that the government assumes full income risk sharing. Bulow and Summers (1986) point out that fluctuations in the value of the asset, referred to as capital risk, are much larger than assumed by FUllerton and Gordon. Variations in stock prices are generally much larger than fluctuations in current income. The findings of Bulow and Summers call into question the assumption of a large amount of income-risk sharing by the government" The fact that Fullerton and Gordon incorporate endogenous financial behavior into their model is clearly an important step forward in the modeling of the U.S. economy. However, although the financial decisions of the firms are endogenized, the investment decisions of the firm are not. If changes in the financial decisions of the firm affect the cost of investment to the firm, the welfare effects of corporate tax integration could be very different from those found by FKSW or Fullerton and Gordon. Slemrod (1983) uses a CGE model to examine the effect of indexing the federal tax system for inflation. One of the major features of his model is the modeling of financial 12 behavior of the corporate sector. In modeling the choice of a firm's debt/equity ratio, Slemrod also relies on the bankruptcy tradeoff theory. As the tax parameters of the model change, the optimal debt/equity levels will change. Slemrod relies on econometric estimates, his own and those of King (1978), of the elasticity of firm's debt levels and dividend payout ratios with respect to changes in the personal and corporate tax rates. Slemrod finds that indexation of the federal income tax system will result in a "significant" reallocation of financial resources. He also finds that indexation results in large welfare gains for upper-income individuals. Although this paper is a major contribution toward CGE modeling, it is lacking in that it groups all corporations into one sector and does not allow for intersectoral variation. Galper, Lucke, and Toder (1988) also use a CGE model to examine the effects of changes in the tax system on a model which incorporates the debt/equity decision of the firm. Their general equilibrium model is used to examine the effects of the 1986 Tax Reform Act. Their modeling of the corporate debt/equity choice differs from Slemrod (1983). Galper, Lucke, and Toder use theoretical considerations to derive explicit demand functions for debt, instead of relying on econometric estimates of firm responses to changes in the tax system. Firms in their model select an optimal debt/equity ratio to minimize the cost of capital, given the interest rate, the corporate tax parameters, and the parameters of 13 individual demand functions for equity. Galper, Lucke, and Toder find that the Tax Reform Act of 1986 resulted in large welfare gains to the upper-income households, because upper- income households tend to hold a disproportionate amount of capital assets. They also find the there should be a slight decline in corporate debt/equity ratios. This is the result of two offsetting effects: a reduction in the corporate income tax, and an increase in the tax rate on capital gains. Although this model proves very useful, it suffers from the same criticisms as Slemrod (1983): the aggregation of the corporate sector and the lack of dynamics in the model. Galper, Lucke, and Toder make an important contribution, however, by using an explicit model of firm debt behavior. Jorgenson and Yun (1986) use an econometrically-estimated general equilibrium model to examine the efficiency of capital allocation among corporate and noncorporate assets. Their model uses empirically estimated production and consumption parameters based on time series data from 1955-1980. A business sector and a household sector are included in their model. The business sector produces consumption and investment goods from labor and corporate and noncorporate capital services. 'The capital services in the business sector are divided among short-lived and long-lived assets. The household sector, in their model, is an aggregate of consumption goods in the economy as well as household capital services, and leisure time. A government sector is also 14 included in their'model. Jorgenson.and Yun examine the impact of the ERTA of 1981. They find that the ERTA of 1981 had potential welfare gains of $542 billion, if a lump-sum tax was used to replace the revenue loss. Using an increase in the tax rate on labor income to recoup the revenue shortfall ‘would result in potential welfare gains of $328 billion, while a sales tax replacement could result in potential welfare gains of $295 billion dollars. The Jorgenson and Yun paper is important, because unlike many other CGE models, it relies on actual empirical estimates of consumer and producer behavior. But, it is does not include endogenous financial behavior. The papers reviewed up to this point have dealt with two major issues, corporate tax integration and CGE :models. Although the modeling of corporate tax integration has improved greatly over the past twenty years, there is still a great amount of work to be done. Table 1 presents a listing of the major features of the CGE models which are discussed here. 1.3.2. Theories of Corporate Financial Leverage This section ‘will give a brief examination of the theories of corporate financial leverage. The corporate leverage decision plays a major role in the development of my model in Chapter 2. 15 The seminal research on corporate financial policy was done by Modigliani and Miller (1958). Their major result was that corporate financial policy is irrelevant in determining the value of the firm, i.e., ceteris paribus, investors will be indifferent to the debt/equity policy or the dividend payout ratio of the firm. Modigliani and Miller's findings are reached under some very restrictive assumptions. They assume: (1) There are perfect capital markets. (2) All bonds are riskless assets. (3) There are no bankruptcy or leverage costs. (4) There are no taxes. The Modigliani-Miller Theorem relies on the ability of investors to borrow and lend to offset any changes in firms' borrowing or dividend policy. Table 1 Summary of Features of Computational General Equilibrium Models Number Endogenous of D/E Endogenous Agthogs Sectors Ratio Dividends Dynamtcg Fullerton, King, Shoven e Whalley (1981) 19 No No Yes Fullerton (1983) 19 No No Yes Fullerton & Gordon (1983) 19 Yes No Yes Slemrod (1983) 5 Yes Yes No Galper, Lucke, and Toder (1988) 5 Yes No No Jorgenson & Yun (1986) 1 No No Yes When corporate and personal taxation are introduced, the Modigliani-Miller Theorem no longer holds. Under the current tax system, interest payments to bondholders are deductible 16 from corporate income, while dividend payments of a firm are not. This makes it cheaper for a firm to use debt than equity. Because debt is the cheaper means of financing an investment, a profit-maximizing firm would finance all of its investments out of debt. Casual observation of the corporate sector shows that this is not the case in the United States. Firms only finance a portion of their capital stock with debt. There are a number of theories on why firms do not finance all of their capital with debt. The existence of agency costs, clientele effects, and bankruptcy costs will be discussed here. The use of large amounts of debt finance may lead to agency costs in the form of distorted investment incentives for firms. One way to reduce these agency costs is to force managers of firms to finance:a portion of their new investment with equity, to preserve some future investment opportunities. The theory of agency costs of this type is discussed by Meyers (1977). Although the current corporate tax law favors the use of debt finance, the existence of personal income taxation may work to reduce the benefits of using debt. The existence of clientele effects, the interaction of personal and corporate tax rates, and the relative costs of debt and equity may also effect corporate debt/equity positions. The effects of personal taxation on corporate financial decisions have been explored by Stiglitz (1973), Miller (1977), and Auerbach and King (1983). 17 Stiglitz (1973) and Miller (1977) focus on the relative costs of borrowing based on the relationship between the corporate income tax rate and personal income tax rate. They point out that certain features of the personal income tax system work to minimize the benefits of using leverage. When a firm uses debt finance, a lower portion of the investment will be taxed as capital gains. Until the Tax Reform Act of 1986, realized capital gains were taxed at a lower rate than interest or dividend income. In addition, capital gains are taxed only on.a:realization basis instead of an accrual basis. This lowers the effective tax rate on equity even further. The existence of a progressive income tax system leads to differing advantages of debt and equity finance for individuals. Because individuals have differing tax rates on bond and equity income, they will want to invest in firms with differing degrees of leverage. This will lead to a market equilibrium with some firms which are very leveraged and some firms that are not very leveraged. Auerbach and King ( 1983) explore the interaction of personal and corporate taxation in a general equilibrium model. Investors in this model select themselves into one of two categories based on their income tax bracket and their personal level of risk aversion. Investors prefer all-debt finance or all-equity finance. Depending on an individual's income class, income from debt may be taxed at a lower rate 18 6 Another major factor in the than equity, or vice versa. selection of the debt/capital ratio is that some investors may be risk averse. If risk aversion is taken into account, investors may put themselves in an all-equity position, even when debt is the tax-preferred form of financing. The existence of differing tax: brackets and levels of risk aversion in the economy will lead, in the aggregate, to some capital being financed with debt and some capital being financed with equity. It is important to note, however, that investors end up in either of two extremes, all-debt or all- equity. This model does not provide for mixed portfolios. The clientele models do not provide for individual firm interior debt/equity positions. This is a major drawback. In the real world, firms do not seek an all-debt or an.all-equity position. In these models, the advantages and disadvantages of using debt stem only from the interaction of the personal and corporate tax systems, and varying levels of risk aversion. The introduction of real costs in the use of debt will lead firms to select an optimal interior debt/capital ratio. The possibility of bankruptcy imposes leverage costs on the firm for using debt. Firms will trade off the tax advantages of using debt against the increase in the 6 Auerbach and King assume that the tax rate on equity is an effective tax rate which combines the lower tax rate on capital gains with a slightly higher rate on dividend income. The tax rate on personal interest income is assumed to be greater than the effective tax rate on equity. However, it is the interaction of the personal and corporate tax rates which leads to a consumer preferring all debt or all equity. 19 probability of bankruptcy (which is assumed to impose real costs on the firm). As mentioned earlier, this theory is explored in Gordon and Malkiel (1981), and adapted to a CGE model in Fullerton and Gordon (1983). The addition of bankruptcy costs may have varying effects across sectors and firms. This will lead to differing leverage positions of firms. I believe that this is an important advantage of the bankruptcy model. Consequently, bankruptcy costs are used in this paper to model firms' leverage decisions. The bankruptcy theory takes into account the asymmetry of the corporate tax code with respect to its treatment of the use of debt and equity by corporations. It also takes into account the effects of the personal income tax system on reducing the tax advantages to investors of firms relying on debt finance, as explored in Stiglitz (1973), Miller (1977), and Auerbach and King (1983). The following is a brief description of a standard version of the bankruptcy theory. Interest income received by bondholders is taxed at their marginal tax rate, 6. The returns to equity holders are taxed in two ways. The portion of the return that is received in the form of dividends, a, is taxed at the marginal tax rate 6. The remaining portion, (1-a), is taxed at the capital gains rate c. Dividend payments are taxed at the corporate level, as corporate income, at the corporate tax rate 1. Interest payments on bonds are deductible from the corporate income tax base, so they are not taxed at the corporate level. The after-tax return on a corporate bond is (1-9)r, where r 20 represents the interest payment on the bond. The after-tax return on equity is {a(1-0)+(1-a) (1-c)}(1-r)r. Note that this model does not take into account any risk, and that the parameter a is assumed to be fixed. Following Fullerton and Gordon (1983), if a firm issues a dollar of debt and then uses that dollar of debt to repurchase a dollar of equity, the gain to investors is (1- 0)r, the new interest payments on the debt, minus {a(1-6)+(1- a)(1-c)}(1-r)r, the reduction in the return to equity. This expression reduces to r{(1-6)-(1-1:)[a(1—e)+(1-a)(1—c)]}. (1) As long as expression (1) is positive, the investors in the firm will gain because the use of debt saves them money. Gordon and Malkiel (1981) explore the conditions under which expression (1) would be positive, or equal zero. As noted in Fullerton-Gordon (1983) , they find that, for reasonable values of the tax rates, expression (1) will be positive. If there were no leverage costs and expression (1) were positive, one would reach the all-debt-finance conclusion. However, with leverage costs, the managers of the firm will realize that they can reduce the cost of acquiring capital by using debt finance, but that this increase in leverage results in real costs to the firm. The bankruptcy costs can be summarized by a function t(o), where o represents the firm's debt/capital ratio. It is assumed that ¢'>0 and t">0. 21 Setting the costs and benefits of debt equal to each other yields the equilibrium condition We» = r{(1-0)-(1-1:)[a(1-8)+(1-a)(1—c)]}. (2) Expression (1) implies that changes in the personal and corporate tax rates will affect the incentive for firms to use debt. The derivative of expression (1) with respect to the corporate tax rate yields7 We’rgeastsjm 1’ =r{a(1-0) +(1-a) (1-c)}. (3) which indicates that an increase in the corporate tax rate will increase the benefits of using debt. It increases the value of the interest deduction on debt, and should lead to an increase in the use of leverage. A change in the personal tax rate (6) will change the taxes that must be paid on interest income and change the taxes that must be paid on dividend income. 6(exprigfion l) = [{(41)+(1-c)(a)} (4) The derivative is clearly negative, indicating that the overall impact of an increase in the personal tax rate is a 7 Note these are partial equilibrium derivatives. In a general equilibrium setting, it will generally not be possible to alter one tax rate without also altering the other tax rates to achieve revenue neutrality. 22 decrease in the benefits of relying on debt finance. This will cause firms to reduce their leverage position. This is because the increase affects the total return to debt, while affecting only a portion of the return on equity. Finally, an increase in the capital gains tax rate should result in an increase in the use of debt because it lowers the after-tax rate of return on equity, but has no effect on the after-tax rate of return on debt. This is shown by equation (5), which is positive, indicating an increase in the benefits of using leverage. 6(1) = r{(1-t) (1-a)} (5) ac Because equation (5) is positive, it indicates that an increase in leverage should result from an increase in the capital gains tax rate. Interest income received by bondholders is taxed at their marginal tax rate. The bankruptcy theory yields empirically testable results with respect to the effect of the personal and corporate tax rates. These results will be tested in Chapter 3. The purpose of this essay is to take the modeling of CGE models and. corporate tax: policies one step further, by presenting a model of firm behavior which can be used in a CGE model. This model will then be used to examine corporate tax policies in a setting where the effects of policies on the financial decisions of the firm, as well as the effects on the 23 investment decisions, are taken into account.8 It will also allow for examination of the dynamic effects of tax integration proposals. The model of firm behavior is presented next. Econometric estimates of the impact of changes in the personal and corporate tax rates on a firm's debt/capital ratio will be obtained from a panel data set of U.S. non-financial corporations covering the period from 1969 until 1988 in Chapter 3. 3 My model does not attempt to explain the dividend behavior of firms, but instead focuses on firms' choices of debt-to-capital ratios. However, the effects of changes in the dividend behavior of the firm may be explored in subsequent work. Chapter 2 MODEL OF FIRM BEHAVIOR This section presents a more complex model of firm behavior. The model encompasses the debt/capital choice of the firm as well as its investment decision. It relies heavily on earlier work by Goulder and Summers (1989), which in turn, is based on Summers (1981). The behavior of firms is based on the premise that managers of firms seek to maximize the value of the firm for its shareholders. I begin. by specifying' the fundamental asset. market equilibrium condition which requires that the after-tax rate of return from ownership in a firm (risk adjusted) must be equal to the rate of return that could be achieved.by' holding a riskless asset, such as a municipal bond. The equilibrium is characterized by (1-c) {V-SN} + (1-6)[Div] -'qV = <1(1-6))v, (6) where c is the capital gains tax rate, V is the change in the value of the firm over time, SN is book-value of new share issues, 6 is the personal tax rate on dividend and interest income, Div are dividends paid by the firm, n is the equity risk premium, which is assumed to be exogenous, V'is the value of the firm, and i is the nominal interest rate. Equation (6) indicates that the after-tax return on capital gains plus the 24 25 after-tax dividend income from the firm (which equals the total net return on the firm), risk adjusted, must equal the after-tax return on the safe asset. Equation ( 6) can be rearranged to yield the differential equation ‘_ I = y_ (1‘6) . V ——(1-c) V S (1_C)D1v, (7) where r = i(1-6) + 7). If one imposes the transversality condition 1' i ' 1 1m -r s-ooo Vs [emf W dUJ = O (8) t to rule out explosive growth in the value of the firm, equation (7) can be solved to yield - 58"] {expf -I" 1 9 r (1-C) leJ dS. ( ) This expression implies that the value of the firm in time t is equal to the present discounted value of the perpetual stream of after-tax dividends less new share issues. Managers will seek to maximize (9) each period. Firms in this model are assumed to maintain a 100 percent dividend-payout ratio. All current after-tax earnings are returned to shareholders in the form of dividend payments. Investment expenditures of the firm are entirely financed out of new debt and new share issues. There are no retained 26 earnings in this model.9 The assumptions of a 100 percent dividend-payout ratio and only new-debt and new-share investment finance place two constraints on the firm: DiV= EARN (1°) and IEXP = B" + s". (11) EARN represents the firm's after-tax earnings, BN represents new bond issues and IEXP represents new investment expenditures. The after-tax earnings of the firm are (PF(K,L,M) -WL-P,,M-1‘D) (1-r) +rDep, (12) where: P = the price of output, F = the production function of the firm, K = capital inputs, L = labor inputs, M = the vector of intermediate inputsw W’= the wage rate, Pk:=‘vector of intermediate input prices, D = nominal debt, r = corporate tax rate, Dep = the value of current depreciation allowances. Investment expenditures are specified as 9The assumption of no retained earnings in this model is important. By not allowing firms to use retained earnings, often thought of the least expensive form of investment finance, one may prevent the firm from undertaking some investment. This may introduce some distortion into the firm's investment decision. 27 IEXP = (1-ITC)PK1'+ (1-r)P¢(TI()I, (13) where ITC is the investment tax credit and ¢( I /K) measures the investment costs per unit of investment. It is assumed that the adjustment costs are homogeneous of degree one in.I and.K. Following Goulder and Summers, I model adjustment costs as being internal to the firm. This implies that, holding constant the amount of investment, an increase in adjustment costs results in a reduction in output. This is due to more inputs being diverted from production to the installation of new capital. I also assume, as do Goulder and Summers, that output, Y, is separable between inputs and adjustment costs, i.e., Y = F0 and Y">0. This function will cause the firm to incur real costs as it increases the share of debt relative to the total value of its capital stock. The bankruptcy costs are modeled as a continuous function of the debt/capital ratio. There is no minimum level of leverage that must be reached before there is a positive probability of bankruptcy. Any positive leverage will result in real costs to the firm.11 Introducing explicit bankruptcy costs also plays an important role in determining how investment is financed. In a similar’model, Goulder and Summers indicate that, due to the tax disadvantages of equity, firms would never issue new shares. This is not the case in this model. Although new shares are disadvantageous from a tax standpoint, they work to the reduce the probability of bankruptcy to the firm. In this model, it is feasible for the reduction in bankruptcy costs, and hence an increase in the value of the firm, to offset the tax disadvantages of issuing new shares. The introduction of bankruptcy costs allows one to rewrite equation (9) as 11 The use of an explicit bankruptcy function makes the model tractable, as well as providing a realistic result: firms achieve an optimal interior debt/capital ratio. 29 [(1—0) . l Vt f ‘1'“ l (1-.» Dw- ' Selle”: W "I" u} ds. (16) Vt now represents the value of the firm when it is not bankrupt. The expression (1-!) represents the probability that the firm will not go bankrupt. It is assumed that if the firm is bankrupt, the value of the finm is equal to zero. Equation (16) indicates that the bankruptcy costs will be proportional to the value of the firm. As the value of the firm.increases, the loss in income that the shareholders would incur if the firm went bankrupt would increase. Therefore, the higher the value of the firm the greater the bankruptcy costs incurred by the firm. In order to specify the value of the firm over time, it is important to represent explicitly the value of allowable depreciation allowances. The depreciation allowances are composed of depreciation allowances on current capital and the value of depreciation allowances on future capital acquisitions. The value of total depreciation allowances in time t is equal to12 12 At this point, I am not concerned with the actual calculation of the value of depreciation allowances. However, when simulations are run, this will become necessary. In order to calculate the present value of depreciation allowances, I‘will appeal to the earlier work of Fullerton.and Henderson (1989), and Hulten and Wykoff (1981). 30 5 Dept = fonmIJeprMt-ul) }du. (17) 0 The parameter 6 represents the exponential depreciation rate under the tax code.13 PR is the price of capital, and I represents the quantity of investment. Equation (17) says that the value of depreciation allowances at time t is equal to sum of the present value of depreciation allowances at each point in time, from time t=0 until current time t. In examining the value of the firm at each point in time, depreciation allowances can be broken down further into depreciation allowances on current capital (Bt) and the value of depreciation on a dollar of capital acquired in the future (2,) . This is done because the value of depreciation expenses on existing capital may be taken as a fixed parameter, because future investment decisions are independent of Bt. This allows the firm to ignore Bt during its value maximization. The value of depreciation expenses on current capital is expressed as Bc=f r86 expl-Ms—tH PK: [(9po (1'—_rc) du} ds. (18) C 13 Note that the tax code does not actually give exponential depreciation rates. The exponential depreciation. rate is used for analytical convenience. See Fullerton and Henderson (1989) for an example of the methodology of transforming depreciation rates. 31 The value of depreciation allowances on future capital acquisitions will affect the cost of future investment, by providing future tax deductions. The expression for the value of depreciation allowances on a dollar of capital acquired in the future is = _ _ ‘I 19 Z, ftuoexp( Mn 3)) [£9po (1_C)da] du. ( ) This expression indicates that the present value of depreciation allowances on a dollar of new investment is equal to the total of the present values at each time period in the future. The earnings of the firm may now be expressed as EARN = (PF(K,L,M) -WL-p,,M-iD) (1-1) +z,p,,1+3t. (20) Substituting earnings into equation (10) implies that dividends are equal to Div = (PF(K,L,M) -WL-P,,M—iD) (1-1) +B+ZPKI. (21) Equation (21) can then be substituted into equation (16) to yield an expression for the value of the firm.at time t. After substituting and rearranging terms, the value of the firm at time t is The managers of the firm will want to maximize equation (22), by selecting L, M, B", I, and SN subject to four 32 vc = fu-wfl 8"” (norm, L, m- WL- -p,,M-1D] (1-1) I: (22) + zprr) — S" J 1{epo--(—1—_———- I ddu}ds+B. constraints: I6 = I-bRK (23) 15=B”-1:D. (24) 3' = S" (25) (1-ITC') prr+(1-r)P¢(-TI() = B” + s" (26) The first constraint, equation (23), is the capital accumulation equation. This indicates that the change in the capital stock is equal to new investment less the depreciated capital stock. Note that 6R is the economic rate of depreciation, which may differ from the depreciation rate allowed under the tax code. Equation (24) gives the change in the value of debt outstanding. It is equal to new debt issues less the decrease in the value of outstanding debt due to inflation, n. The third constraint, equation (25), indicates that the change in value of shares outstanding is equal to the value of new share issues. The final constraint insures that investment expenditures will be equal to the value of new'debt plus new shares. 33 The maximization problem of the firm can be solved by applying Pontryagin's maximum principle. I set up a current- value Hamiltonian and introduce three multipliers, 11 12, and 13, which are interpreted as the shadow prices of capital, shares, and debt respectively. I also introduce a static multiplier, p, to account for the fourth constraint. Because the depreciation allowances on the current capital stock (Be) are independent of future investment choices, they can be ignored in the firm's maximization problem. The firm then selects L, M, I, S", and BN to maximize f -r H g {3- We“ duh {1-T}{:—::—2—;—<[PF(K,L,M) -WL-P,,M—iD] (1-1) +ZPKI+>- + 11(1-6“) + 12(3") + 13(BN-1CD) + B{(1-ITC)P,.I+(1-r)P¢(7I()I-S"-B”ll. (27) Maximization yields the following first-order conditions: 5H. E. FL=%’ ‘28) 65:1”: 13 = (3 (30) 11: -(1-T) iii); ZPX - B{(1—ITC)PK+(1—I)P {¢+(-I€,)o’}} Bias (31) 34 3H. . R _ (1-6) 32.1 111(—(——fc)+6) (1- T)cK-—TPF(1(1_1:-)+ 2 (32) I - (ml-mu?) «V1 6H _ I (1- 6) 1 -a—D.:1.313(——(1_c) +1!) --(1 ‘1’) (1_ C)(-1')(1- 'c) + ‘P(—( S)2)X (33) 8H —63N:B = 12-(1-1’) (34) OH I / D 6? ‘2‘ “(Tr-75$" * "' ‘W’X‘ "5’ In first-order conditions (33) and (35), Xt is equal to current earnings less the book-value of new share issues. First-order conditions (28) and (29) imply that labor and intermediate outputs should be used up to the point where their marginal products equal their respective input prices. Using the first-order conditions for new debt and new shares, one can solve equations (33) and (35) for the value of H, the static multiplier. Equations (33) and (35) can then be combined to achieve the condition v’<—S——)x,-T’(—£— (D+S)2 (D +S S)2 r + _(1— 0) _ (1-c) ‘n -(1_ C)(i)(1 1)} )Jsr,{1———’t ”’0’ }= I (36) (1-T){ This expression represents the marginal costs and benefits of transferring a dollar of equity to a dollar of debt. The 35 left-hand side represents the increase in bankruptcy cost. The right-hand side represents the gain from using debt. The first term represents the required after-tax rate of return that would have been paid on a new share. The second term represents the benefits of inflation on debt. During periods of inflation, the real value of outstanding debt decreases. This causes the benefit of using debt to increase. The final term represents the value of the interest payment on the dollar of debt. This expression implies that a firm should select its level of debt such that the marginal increase in leverage costs on the left-hand side of the equation are just equal to the marginal advantages of using debt on the right- hand side of the equation. ‘This equation implies that changes in the personal and corporate tax rates will affect the firm's debt/capital ratios. This effect will be measured empirically in Chapter 3. Next, I solve for the investment equation of the firm. Note that equation (22), the value of the firm, is homogeneous of degree one in all inputs K, L, M, and I. This is the result of the constant returns to scale production function and the homogeneous adjustment cost function. This implies that ‘the ‘value of 'the firm. minus the ‘value of current depreciation is proportional to the value of the capital stock, or (Vt-BC) =nyK, (37) 36 where y is the factor of proportionality, or average q. The maximum principle and the definition of the shadow price imply that 6Vt_ am: "A" t (38) Equations (37) and (38) imply that marginal and average q are equivalent.’4 Because average and marginal q are equal in this model, equations (37) and (38) can be combined to yield __ (Vt-BC) lint PK (39) Included in equation (39) is the value of the firm, after taxes, relative to the value of the capital stock. This is known as Tobin's marginal q adjusted for taxes, or what Summers (1981) refers to as "tax-adjusted Q." This expression can then be substituted into the first- order condition for investment, along with the value of 8 derived from equations (34) and (35), to yield an investment equation of the form In order to specify the investment equation completely, I must specify the adjustment cost function completely. I adopt the adjustment.cost function first introduced by Summers (1981). It is assumed that adjustment costs are zero until 1‘ In this model, average and marginal q will always be equivalent. However, it is important to note that empirical evidence has shown that marginal and average:q often.differ in the real world. 37 l 1 IQ -'Bt (1’3) WW3) + «M = { + (1-Y)——z1 K l (14) - w't—D >X. P22" (1'9) (ms)2 + ( 1 + ITC)? ]———l ' ‘JP(1-t) (40) some level of investment and then rise linearly; The adjustment cost function is assumed to be m I —((—)-¢vz)2 ¢(TI{)= 2 K (41) NIH Because adjustment costs have been specified,the investment function can be derived by substituting for ¢(I/K) in equation (40). .After substituting and.rearranging'terms, equation (40) reduces to the investment function -I£(=a+ Q , (42’ eIH where Q represents the right-hand side of equation (40) and o and a are estimated adjustment cost parameters. This investment function can then be used to model the response of firms to changes in tax policy. Econometric estimates of the change in a firm's leverage position with respect to changes in personal and corporate tax parameters can also be used to fully specify the value of the firm.ambedded in the investment function. 38 The next section examines empirically the implications of the effect of corporate and personal taxation on firms' leverage decisions implied by equation (36). Chapter 3 THE EFFECT OF PERSONAL AND CORPORATE TAXES ON FIRMB' DEBT/CAPITAL RATIOS 3.1. Empirical Implications of the Bankruptcy Models Equation (36) implies that changes in the personal and corporate tax rates will affect the benefits that firms receive from the use of leverage. The effects of changes in the tax rates generated from my model do not differ from those that are predicted by expression (1). This can be seen by examining the effects of changes in the personal and corporate tax rates on the benefits of using leverage. Define P as the benefits of using leverage. Gamma is equal the right-hand side of equation (36), _ _ r _ (1-6) - _ I‘ - (1 ‘1’) {_M + a: (1_C) (1) (1 1)}. (43) Differentiation of equation (43) with respect to the marginal personal tax rate 6 yields15 3(P) _ _ _ i r 3767‘ (”WT—7:7 “" Equation (44) indicates that an increase in the personal tax rate will decrease in the advantages of using'debt. This Will result.in.a decrease in a firm's debt/capital ratio. iBoth.the 15 This uses the fact that r = (1-6)i + n. 39 40 simple bankruptcy model and.my model of firm behavior predict that an increase in the capital gains tax rate and the corporate tax rate will result in an increase in the use of leverage. It may appear that.the construction of my model was simply a theoretical excise which could have been avoided, because it reaches the same empirical implications as the simple bankruptcy model. However, although the theoretical predictions of both models are similar, my model provides a framework for the tax policy simulations which are conducted in Chapter 5. In this chapter, I will examine empirically the role of taxation in the firm's choice of debt/capital ratios. 3.2. Estimation 3.2.1. Mgggl A fixed-effects model was used to measure the responsiveness of the corporations to changes in the tax rates. The model takes the form: Yit=pXic+Ai+aT+€ic a (‘5’ Yit is a measure of the ith firm's debt/capital ratio in year t. lit is a vector containing information on firm sales, corporate and personal tax rates, and a measure of inflation. A time trend, T, is also included. The cit denotes the firm- and year-specific random error. These errors are assumed to 41 be distributed 'N(0,02). Lambda (1.1) represents a firm- specific effect that is assumed to be time invariant. This effect allows the estimation.to»account for the fact that some firms may have consistently high or low debt/capital ratios, over time, due to a firm-specific characteristic. The fixed-effect model is estimated by differencing each firm's observations around the individual means in the following way:16 (46) This differencing will remove the fixed effect because it is time invariant. The resulting model is then estimated using ordinary least squares“ The natural logarithms of all variables are used, with the exception of the time trend, so that the resulting coefficients are in elasticity form. 3.2.2. Data Estimation was performed on a panel data set consisting of annual data from 1969 to 1988. Firm-specific data were obtained from Standard and Poor's 1989 COMPUSTAT data tape. Information on a firm's outstanding debt as well as its 1‘ Note that this differencing is done for all variables, not just the X and Y vectors. 42 current capital stock and sales was collected. The firms were separated into twelve sectors, according to their Standard Industrial Classification (SIC). The separation into sectors is to control for sector-specific effects. In Table 2, I provide a listing of the sectors, the number of firms in each sector, and the SIC codes for each sector. The debt variable for each firm includes both long- and short-term debt, and is based on the book value of the company's debt. The value of the current capital stock is equal to the value of outstanding debt, plus equity, plus any minority interest of the firm. Data on annual sales were obtained for each firm, to control for firm size as well as for fluctuations in business activity. Because the sales variable is used to control for firm size, it was adjusted using the Consumer Price Index (CPI), as reported in LYLE fitatiatigal Absttact of the Qaitea States. In addition, the annual percentage change in the CPI was included to control for the effects of inflation on debt/capital ratios. During periods of inflation, the real value of a firm's outstanding debt will decrease. If firms are concerned with maintaining a debt/capital ratio in real terms, they may issue more debt during inflationary periods. Table 3 contains time—series information on the debt/capital ratios of each sector. The data indicate the differences in the use of debt between sectors. The average debt/capital ratios over the sample period range from .29 in the chemical, rubber, and plastics sector, to .52 in the 43 transportation, communications, and utilities sector. .Almost all sectors show growth in the use of leverage during the sample period, especially in the late 1980's. One may note, however, that even given the growth in debt/capital ratios, the variation over time appears limited. Data on corporate tax rates were obtained from Pechman (1987). The top marginal corporate tax rate was used for each year. unfortunately, this variable shows little variation over the twenty-year period, changing only four times. The statutory rate is the variable of choice. In my model, the statutory rate is the rate which.will affect the value of the interest deduction for the firm. Note that, in my model, changes in the depreciation schedules and investment tax credit have no effect on firms' leverage positions. There may be second-order effects, but those effects are not investigated here. Data on personal marginal tax rates were obtained by updating the series of average marginal tax rates compiled by Barro and Sahasakul (1983). They build a time series of average marginal tax rates weighted by the amount of adjusted 44 Table 2 Listing of Corporate Sectors Used in Estimation figctor .. .. .flgsoge__ W Food and Tobacco 2000 - 2141 33 (Food) Textiles, Apparel, and 2200 - 2399 & 31 Leather 3100 - 3199 (Text) Paper and Printing 2600 - 2796 46 (Paper) Petroleum Refining 2910 - 2911 & 23 (Refine) 2992 - 2999 Chemicals, Rubber, and 2800 - 2899 71 Plastics 3000 - 3089 (Chemical) Lumber, Furniture, Stone, 2400 - 2599 & 22 Clay, and Glass 3200 - 3299 (Lumber) Metals, Machinery, 3300 — 3699 8 209 Instruments, and Misc. 3800 - 3999 Manufacturing (Metal) Transportation Equipment 3720 - 3799 23 (Transportation) Motor Vehicles 3710 - 3716 19 (Motor) Transportation, 4000 - 4971 187 Communications, and Utilities (Communications) Wholesale and Retail Trade 5000 - 5999 81 (Trade) Services 7000 - 8999 35 (Services) TOTAL: 780 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1986 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 Avg: Std. 0". KEY: £1 1! EB 28 .35 .42 .31 .36 .39 .38 .32 .39 .36 .37 .33 .37 .37 .41 .31 .36 .36 .44 .30 .35 .41 .44 .31 .33 .35 .35 .30 .34 .33 .40 .30 .35 .33 .42 .30 .36 .36 .43 .29 .36 .39 .43 .27 .34 Food and Tobacco Textiles Paper and Printing Motor Vehicles Services Communications Petroleum Refining Chemicals Lumber Metals Manufacturing Trade Table 3 . Summary of Debt/Capital Ratios by Sector 1969-1988 45 51 34 56 33 32 35 so 35 32 52 15 a! 33 .33 .32 £9 .56 .56 .56 .55 .55 .58 .55 .52 .50 .50 .51 .50 .51 .50 .03 std. 46 gross income of each marginal bracket. They construct tax rates for 1916 through 1980. I extend their data through 1988. Data on the highest marginal tax rate paid by gross income group are obtained from the U.S. Department of Treasury's W. The average marginal rate is obtained by using the formula i-n 72; (AGIi/AGI) Ti, (47) -1 where the subscript i refers to the adjusted gross income class, AGIi refers to the adjusted gross income of class i, AGI refers to total adjusted gross income, T1 refers to the highest marginal tax rate paid by that class, and T is the average marginal tax rate. This equation corresponds to Barro and Sahasakul's equation (11). The capital gains tax rate was based on.the effective tax rate on capital gains after allowing for the capital gains exclusion. Between 1969 and 1978, the rate was 50% of the personal tax rate, due to the 50% exclusion of capital gains income. Between 1979 and 1986, the rate was 40% of the personal rate because of the 60% exclusion. In 1987 and 1988, the capital gains and.personal tax rates were identicall Data on the highest marginal rate paid by adjusted gross income class were not available for 1987 and 1988. These amounts had to be imputed based on the average taxable income of each 47 adjusted gross income class. The average marginal tax rate was then calculated using equation (47). 3-2-3- W The results of the initial regressions are presented in Table 4. They show that, in four of the twelve sectors (metal, communications, transportation equipment, and lumber), the coefficients on the personal income tax rate were significant and negative. The coefficients on the inflation measure, CPI, ranged from 0.02 to 0.20. They indicate that, during times of inflation, firms slightly increase their debt loads. The trend variable does not indicate any overall trend in the debt/capital ratios, but instead emphasizes the differences between sectors“ In the sectors of refining and lumber, there was a positive trend in the debt/capital ratios over the sample period. In the communications and transportation sectors, there was a downward trend in the debt/capital ratios. The results from the basic model were not overwhelmingly strong. In order to improve my estimates, I attempted a number of different approaches, including correcting for autocorrelation, aggregation, and estimating lag models. One possible reason for the insignificance of many of the coefficients may be the presence of autocorrelation in the data. In order to test for autocorrelation, the correlation 118 .80... dance. ¢.¢L_e a a modem uuceau as.» aooc__ n ucoa» uxouc_ ou.ca Loesacou use c_ vac-go acoocoa u _au unc_ou .au_eeo co one; xou socoaaoa u chug “one; xeu ouecoeaou u «bu "Queue. ucoo_s_o a acetone. co one; xau seepage: a «pa .aooogucoaoa c. uumuo_uouu.p u.o>o. moo we ucoo_*_cuwn aoueu_nc_ c u.o>os xmo us acao_v_copa noueo_ucm ac nmN.~v ANN.v A—a.nv arm.v now.v Aem.pv mo. oo.w aeno.. no. team. or. «P. 0¢.- moum>eom an6.nv AOm.wv nop.ov aqw.pv Aop.~v A¢~.Pv no. nh.P cano.. no. on. eOM.- eeo.P- nQ. gonna Aoo.wv Ao¢.~v Acm.nv new.v Anh.v Anv.wv oo. aeoo.¢ No. stow. sann.. no. no.- 95v.- modumgo> Laue: “on.~v nm¢.nv «mo.~v Am¢.Nv Aop.~v Amm.~v mo. et0.N «ewe. temp. acne. acne. can.« ae~o.u 500534 8.}... 2%: 3%.: at: $3 5.8 8:955“ ON. eeon.~— eemo.. cp.u sam¢. mm. kn.- sea—.9- compoueonocoL» ah.~v Acm.Pv Aoo.nv Ao~.v Aco.Pv App.v no. eNF.N echo. oo. seen.. 00. an. no. acycmwox mop.v a¢0.pv “No.v Aeo.v ANM.FV am.pv «o. 00." ~06. so. no. n~.- ¢.r- no. 090000» a team n~¢.Pv Ann.wv Aom.nv “No.v Amh.pv Am~.v Fo. eao¢.n «we.. «0.- «the. «v.1 aoQ.- 0o. once» Aoc.cv A0.-u Ace..wv anh.pv a—Q.v Ahn.nv up. eeu~.¢~ oanoo.- two. No.. .00. mc.- sen~.- comuuumcaaaou «ca.wv An¢.nv Aho.pv Aoo.~v num.pv Aoa.nv no. eeu~.pp one. stop. nee. sewn. no. eeoo.- dawn: «00.0.v Ao~.~v “kn.0v «Nm.pv A0¢.OV “om.0v ma. ee-.m '00.- seep.o «0.0- o¢.o «Q. o-.- madmaxoh nNM.Ou Ah—.pv Aho.wv acm.0v Amm.oV mop.0v No. no.0 n6.o no.6 eaoo.o ow.o- hm.o. no.0 doouiusu «a b_u a unucouc_ co one; x.» .ac_ocex a a»; .ooaozucocaa c_ nowua_uaua-» u.o>o. goo ua uceu_e_cu_u nouoo_uc. c u.o>o. xmo an acou_»_co.o nouoo_uc_ cc “~0.pv Rom.v “on.bv aon.v aen.v “00.0 00. ow.w e~0.- ~0.- aawu. N0. 0N. n¢.- mauu>eom «ms-Nu Ane.wv abo.nv Aow.Pv ANN.FV as~.wv N0. 50.? ee~0.- m0.- eecm. 0w.- s~o.- 0n. canoe awn.» aho.~v Amo.—v a¢¢.v “00.0 “mo-v no. 00.— F0. econ. cop.- m¢.- w0.p- vn.- modu_co> Laue: Aph.v A00.~v A0~.¢v nm0.Pv Aoo.wv n-.~v 00. m0.— 000. stop. MN. «mm. e~0.P seno.- cones; 5.8 83 3nd :3 8m; 2:. 5 85.633 00. ecum.¢ cae0.- ~0.- sane. 0w. m¢.- ewh.- comu0ucoamcoc» Amn.Nv «Fm.Pv AQF.¢V n0¢.0 Ao~.Fv “op.v m0. 00.w ee~0. 00. sewn.- 0'. no. 00.- ocmcmwum «nu. .anh.Fv “on.~v “no.0 Amn.pv no¢.v m0. ho.- 000. ako. «sew. o-.- «0.- m—. ouoonoh a nook ans. amm0.0 Ah¢.mv nmh.v nhw.v 500.Fv F0. n~.w Q00. «00.- .600. 00. N0. 0«.- coach Ann.~v “50.nv abn.nv AOM.v awo.v nhp.~v no. and «£30.- eemwo. .53.- ..0. N0: tsp...- cannot-£300 amw.nv ~nm.nv n0¢.v AoF.~v “0F.~v «om.cv n0. econ.0 compo. aeww. caMN. p90. sank. seNN.- douuz a00.wv A04.~v Am0.0 ~00.Fv “00.90 “00.0 M0. enN.~ ~w0. nu. ~0.- awe. 00. 0m.- mudmuxoh and. and.pv Anm.w0 “on.v Aco.v n0¢.v F0. smo- 000. Como. N00. 0e0. ON. 0F.- doumlucu «a hS—m-m “3...; ~00 mud; «.50 5.0 Eh LOuuom Owuou Houunoo\unom m.auwm o a“ mammauo> unocsoaon moduuaouuooouad How usauoouuoo Hound uuasaoa soduaouwoa o mmxama 53 resulted in less significant coefficient estimates. In addition, only two of the F-statistics on the vector of tax rates were significant at the 90% level. These results indicate that controlling for sectoral differences is important. In addition to the correction for autocorrelation and aggregation, one- and two-period lag models were estimated for every sector. These lag models were constructed as Yit = B1X1c+pzxi,t-1+a1T+V1c (50) for a one-period lag. Construction of the two-period lag model was similar. The results of these regressions indicate that current values of the tax rates have a larger impact on corporate debt/capital ratios than lagged values. This result is consistent with earlier work by Auerbach (1985). Auerbach uses a panel data set on 200 corporations, covering 1958-1977, to examine the speed of adjustment of corporate leverage to changes in the corporate tax system. A partial adjustment model is used to measure the impact of changes in depreciation allowances on structures and equipment, as well as variance and.growth.rates of earnings on short- and long-term.debt. .Auerbach finds that firms are very quick. to adjust. their' debt load. as changes in ‘the ‘tax structure occur. Because Auerbach is more concerned with the speed of adjustment than with the magnitude of change, his results are not directly comparable to mine. Auerbach also 54 examines the effect of net loss carryforwards on corporate debt policy. A firm which has a large carryforward may be exempt from the corporate income tax. This may reduce the incentive for a firm to use debt as a way to reduce its tax liability, because the use of debt has no impact on a firm's current taxable income, which is already zero. He finds that the existence of net loss carryforwards does reduce a firm's use of leverage. In order to account for this finding in my model, the data set was reduced by eliminating all firms which possessed a net loss carryforward during the sample period. This reduced the sample size significantly to 482 firms. .A new set of regressions was run with these data. The results did not differ substantially from the original regressions. The signs and magnitudes of the coefficients in each sector were very close to their values before adjusting for net loss carryforwards. Therefore, these results are not presented here. 3.3. Conclusions The attempts at estimating the impact of changes in tax rates on debt/capital ratios have shown that firms do not exhibit a large deal of sensitivity to changes in statutory tax rates. The most encouraging result is that the strongest results in terms of significance and magnitude come from the 55 largest sector, the metal sector with 209 firms. The F-tests indicate that the interaction of the personal and corporate tax rates do affect the debt/capital ratios of the firms in those sectors. The results also appear to point out the need for further research in the area of empirical estimation of the effects of taxation on corporate leverage decisions. The results from this section may be used as base case parameter estimates in the simulation model. Sensitivity analysis can then be used to examine the effects of changes in firm behavior on the tax integration proposals. Chapter 4 DESCRIPTION OF THE SIMULATION MODEL 4.1. Introduction The purpose of this section is to describe the CGE model which is used to simulate the effects of corporate tax integration in a dynamic framework. This model is a modified version of the CGE model described in Ballard, Fullerton, Shoven and Whalley ( 1985) . It incorporates features of my model of firm financial behavior, described in Chapter 2, and also the empirical results of Chapter 3. Because my model does not focus on the inter-generational effects of corporate tax integration, I choose to use an infinite-horizon model of consumer behavior, rather than an overlapping generations model. A. model incorporating infinite-horizon consumer behavior is described in Ballard and Goulder (1985) and Ballard (1990). 4.2. The Consumer's Problem The consumer in the model strives to maximize lifetime utility. The consumer is assumed to have an additively- separable lifetime utility function of the form: 56 5'7 .. I 1 v‘ 23 W Wt" ‘5" p where p is the subjective rate of time preference and Ct is consumption in time t. An isoelastic utility function is chosen in order to insure tractability. The consumer's instantaneous utility can be represented as - (Ct_Cct)1-O ‘ 1-6 ’ 5’1 (52) Ut=ln(Cc-Cc‘) , 6:1, where 6 is the inverse of the elasticity of substitution between consumption in adjacent periods. Consumers have a minimum amount of required consumption in period t of C*t. The existence of a minimum required level of consumption may reduce the excessive intertemporal sensitivity that sometimes characterizes models of this type. See Starrett (1982). Combining equation (51) and equation (52) yields the consumer's lifetime utility function: ~ - ea 1 (Ct—Cct)1'5 53 U"; (mm-1 1-6 ' ( ’ 58 It is important to note that p is assumed to be constant. This assumption is necessary in order to make the consumer's behavior dynamically consistent in the sense of Strotz (1955) . The consumer maximizes his lifetime utility subject to a budget constraint, which insures that the present value of lifetime consumption is less than or equal to the present value of lifetime wealth. The consumer's lifetime budget constraint is given by t “1 H (hrs) " I] <1+r,> 8'1 8'1 " pth " thti-Yt SW I 2 c 1 + Z... (54) where pt is the price of consumption in period t, r is the 8 rate of return in period s, W1 is the value of initial capital, wt is the wage in period t, Ht is the hours of labor supplied in period t, and itt is the value of transfers received in period t18. Note that there are no borrowing constraints in this model. I-It is specified exogenously for each period. It is specified to grow at a constant rate E. This rate accounts 18 The wealth of physical capital in this model differs from that used in earlier versions of the GEMTAP model. The capital the consumer owns is financial capital. The consumer is assumed to hold both corporate debt and equity. Because the after-tax rate of return is equivalent on both instruments, for a given set of taxes, the consumer demonstrates no preference for either. This allows firms to adjust their debt/capital ratios freely in response to changes in the structure of the tax system. 59 for both population growth as well as productivity growth, because labor is specified in efficiency units. The model of consumer behavior will be well behaved as long as E < r, the rate of return which prevails in the long run. If this were not the case, the present value of wealth would be infinite, and there would be no effective constraint on lifetime consumption. A Langrangean can be formed from equations (53) and (54) with Ct as the choice variable. The Langrangean yields the following first-order condition for consumption: 6L 1 . -a Ap- ———:-——————— Cf-C = . 30. (1+p)*1( ‘ J t (55) H (1+r,) 8-1 This marginal condition is rearranged as follows: AP (1+p )“1 C _Cs '0: t t . ( t C) (56) C H (1+r3) 8-1 One can then examine the relationship between consumption in any two adjacent periods: (CC- Cc‘) (Cc-1'Ct-1‘) Pt-l (1+Ic)1'i' Pc (1+p)J =[ (57) Equation (57) can be solved recursively to yield an equation of motion for discretionary consumption. This is 60 1 (Ct-Cc.) = (C1_C10)oc-E' (58’ where C P H (l+r,) (59) = s-i _l. , c P: (1+P)t'1 Discretionary consumption in period one can be found by substituting the equation of motion into the lifetime budget constraint. This substitution yields: as C 2 [(WJIC‘+Yc-ptCt‘)1—I (1+r,) -1]+W1 C1-C1. = t=1 ' I 1 t 8:1 1 (so, «‘12;th cTH (1+r,)'1.J 8-1 Equation (60) can then be used to solve for consumption in period one, as well as consumption in future periods, given the time paths for the price of consumption, the wage rate, the endowments, and the rate of return. 4.3. Producer's Problem This section describes the incorporation of the essential features of the ‘model of firm investment and financial behavior described in Chapter 2. This model has nine distinct production sectors which are constructed as aggregates of the 61 original nineteen sectors of the GEMTAP model described in BSFW (1985) . The aggregation is done using the capital stocks of the sectors as weights. Table 7 lists the production sectors and the GEMTAP components used in their construction.19 The production sectors are classified as corporate, noncorporate, or owner-occupied housing, for the purposes of tax treatment. This classification makes it very easy to follow the flow of capital between corporate and noncorporate sectors. This model does not examine the effects of sectors containing both corporate and noncorporate firms.20 The production sectors, with the exception of the owner-occupied housing sector, are classified as corporate or noncorporate based.on the proportion of the total capital stock within each sector that is held by corporate and noncorporate entities. Sectors where less than 68 percent of the capital stock was incorporated were placed in the noncorporate sector. Although 68 percent is a large cutoff, it was chosen to insure that 19 The ninth production sector in this model is government enterprises. This sector functions exactly as it does in the earlier versions of the GEMTAP model. For this reason, it is excluded from the description of the production sector. 20 The interaction of corporate and noncorporate firms within the same sector has been investigated by Gravelle and Kotlikoff(1989) . They find that taking into account the existence of corporate and noncorporate capital in the same sector is important. As noted earlier, their results may be due to aggregation bias, or other factors besides the existence of both corporate and noncorporate capital within the same sector. 62 there would be several production sectors which were classified as noncorporate. The implication of reducing the required percentage of noncorporate capital is explored as part of the sensitivity analysis. Data on the breakdown between the corporate and noncorporate capital within each sector were obtained from Fullerton and Henderson (1987) . Table 8 presents data on the capital stocks and the division between corporate and noncorporate ownership. Production in each sector is specified by a constant elasticity of substitution value-added function of the form: 0-1 0'1 0 VA=¢lnLT+(1-H)K7]fi. “1’ where ¢ and u are sector-specific production parameters and a is the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital. Each production sector produces a single output under constant-returns-to-sca1e technology. Producers face gross— of—tax input prices of PL" and PK". Each firm minimizes input between the corporate and noncorporate capital within each sector were obtained from Fullerton and Henderson (1987) . Table 8 presents data on the capital stocks and the division between corporate and noncorporate ownership. Production in each sector is specified by a constant elasticity of substitution value-added function of the form: 0-1 0-1 a VA=¢[|JLT+(1—|1)K—°_)°_‘1, “2’ PRODUCTION SECTORS EBQDQQIIQE_§E£IQB§ PRIMARY (1) (2) (3) CONSTRUCTION (4) NONDURABLES (5) (6) (7) (3) (9) DURABLES (10) (11) (12) (13) TRANSPORTATION, (14) COMMUNICATION, AND UTILITIES TRADE (15) OWNER-OCCUPIED (16) HOUSING (17) SERVICES (18) GOVERNMENT (19) ENTERPRISES 63 TABLE 7 USED IN THE SIMULATION MODEL GEMTAP CQMEQNEHIS Agriculture, Forestry, and Fisheries Mining Crude, Petroleum,and Gas Construction Food and Tobacco Textiles, Apparel, and Leather Paper and Printing Petroleum Refining Chemicals and Rubber Lumber, Furniture, Stone, Clay, and Glass Metals and Machinery Transportation Equipment Motor Vehicles Transportation, Communication, and Utilities Wholesale and Retail Trade Real Estate Finance and Insurance Services Government Enterprises 64 where o and n are sector-specific production parameters and a is the elasticity of substitution between labor and capital. Each production sector produces a single output under constant-returns—to-scale technology. Producers face gross- Of-tax input prices of PL’" and PK". Each firm minimizes input costs per unit Of output subject to the value-added constraint. A Lagrangean can be set up with K and L as the Choice variables. 0-1 _ o_-1 A EE=P;K+pU‘L+1[¢()-L ° +(1-p)K a ) ad.” (63) TABLE 8 Breakdown Of Capital Stock Classification by Sector INDUSTRY CORPMTE NONCORPORATE HOJS 1 110 TOTAL PERCENT CMPCRATE Primary $88,274.80 $444,606.10 0.00 $532,880.90 16.57 Construction 13,410.74 6,458.87 0.00 19,869.61 67.49 londurables 158,272.50 2,843.17 0.00 161,115.60 98.24 Durables 199,882.40 3,485.08 0.00 203,367.50 98.29 Transportation, 315,647.60 24,586.53 0.00 340,234.10 92.77 Communication, 8 Utilities Trade 132,785.80 32,384.05 0.00 165,169.90 80.39 Owner-Occupied 0.00 0.00 1,660,132.00 1,660,132.00 MIA Services 66,412.73 45,275.36 111,688.10 59.46 assassssssass 83333333838=8 :==s:==:====: assassssxxsss usages-sag TOTALS 974,686.57 559,639.16 1,660,132.00 3,194,457.73 * All figures in millions Of dollars 65 The Lagrangean yields the following first-order conditions for labor and capital: 83 £'_1 .142 _L :1 E? P,“ = ~A¢(l—p.) [11L " +(1—p.)K ° ] 1’°K ° (54) 35¢ 11- fl ° ’_1 '5': PL‘ = -l¢uluL ° +<1-u)K ° 1 1"’13 ° “5’ Dividing 'the first-order' conditions 'yields ‘the following marginal condition: _‘_1 PK.= (1-”)K a . p: 2. L 11L" 1“) This condition can be solved for capital or labor and then substituted back into the constraint to yield the following per unit factor demands: DK=¢-1[I1{ (1‘11) PL }1-°+(1’1‘)] 1-a (67) l4 P“ and D =