RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EFFECTS OF ICT ON BILATERAL TRADE By Tithi Chattopadhyay A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Media and Information Studies – Doctor of Philosophy 2013       ABSTRACT RESHAPING INSTITUTIONS: EFFECTS OF ICT ON BILATERAL TRADE By Tithi Chattopadhyay Internet and telecommunication technologies have changed the way people communicate and do business across the globe. This technology revolution has been visible not only in high income countries, but also in developing and lower income countries. It has impacted business transactions between these groups of countries. This dissertation studies the effect of the Internet on bilateral trade. A few studies have looked at the impact of the Internet on bilateral trade. This study offers a novel analysis of its interactions with the institutional underpinnings of trade by examining the effects of Internet use on trade in industries that require varying degrees of relationship-specific investments. Industries can be categorized by their level of dependence on investments that are relationship-specific. A higher dependence on relationship-specific investments is generally associated with higher levels of risk in the transaction process. Countries with more stable and differentiated institutional arrangements are generally capable of better contract enforcement, and have often been the preferred trading partner in such industries. This study analyzes whether Internet use impacts industries with a higher need for institutional arrangements differently from those that have a smaller need for these institutional arrangements. Internet is able provide access to different kinds of information (verbal and visual) almost instantly, and this plays a role in reducing transaction costs (traditionally managed through the use of institutional arrangements between two countries). The underlying conceptual framework of this study takes into account the affordances of the technology based on past literature. The effect of these affordances or     features on coordination costs, information costs and productivity costs is analyzed to develop the hypothesis for this study. The adopted approach analyzes the impact of internet use on institutional intensive sectors by understanding the relationship of these different technological affordances on transaction and production costs in an industry. A pooled OLS estimation and panel data estimation using gravity specifications of international trade was performed on 25 industries and for 72 countries between the time periods 2002 to 2010. The findings indicate that higher Internet use by the exporting country has a positive impact on trade with the US in sectors that require higher institutional arrangements. This has important policy implications because countries with relatively poorer institutional arrangements can now benefit from the use of Internet, as the technology is able to reduce transaction and information costs to some degree. It also implies that the use of Internet or broadband could reduce the need for stronger institutional arrangements in industries with relationship-specific investments. The findings from this study also suggest that industries with low institutional intensities are positively impacted by the use of the Internet because of its effect on productivity particularly in markets that are highly competitive in nature. The underlying cause and reason for impact on industries with a lower need for institutional arrangements is a little more ambiguous because of multiple factors that can influence the outcome including the nature of the industry (competitive or not) and the existence of other potential importers in the market.     ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The past few years of being a PhD student have taught me life skills beyond the obvious academic ones. A lot of people have helped me and influenced me during this time and have made my experience deeper and richer. I have met a lot of inspiring people that have challenged me to broaden my horizons and change my worldview. This section is dedicated to those individuals that I owe my deepest gratitude towards. First of all, I would like to thank Dr. Johannes Bauer for mentoring me and keeping me on track throughout the course of my PhD program. His patience and guidance helped me through this experience that can be somewhat challenging at times. I would also like thank the tireless efforts of my committee members Dr. Steve Lacy, Dr. Steve Wildman and Dr. Kurt DeMaagd. I have been fortunate to have had worked with all of them on other projects besides this dissertation, and I have learnt a lot from each one of them. I am also very grateful to my loving family. I would first of all like to thank my parents for pretty much everything! They have supported me and inspired me even though they were miles and time zones apart. I would also like to thank my extended family and friends (the list is long so I will not mention everyone) that have encouraged me and kept me sane through all this. Finally, I would like to thank Shishir for the million big and little things he has done for me during this process! I really do not think I could have begun and finished this without the support of all these wonderful people. iv     TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES vi LIST OF FIGURES vii 1. INTRODUCTION 1 2. LITERATURE REVIEW 2.1 Internet and communication technology and economic productivity 2.2 ICT and its effect on trade 2.3 Importance of Institutions in trade 2.4 Research Questions and Contribution of this Study 8 9 13 17 21 3. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK 3.1 Affordances of the Internet (broadband technology) 3.2 ICT and its impact on trade costs 3.2.1 Effect on Transaction Costs 3.2.2 ICT and its impact on aggregate productivity 3.3 Institutional arrangements in trade and broadband technology 3.4 Impact of Internet technology: Overall conceptual framework 3.5 Hypothesis to be tested 23 24 27 29 33 36 38 44 4. METHODOLOGY 48 5. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE 55 6. CONCLUSION 71 APPENDICES Appendix A: Panel Regression Results Appendix B: OLS Regression Results Appendix C: Summary Statistics 75 76 98 123 REFERENCES 167 v     LIST OF TABLES Table 1 Affordances of broadband and effect on coordination and information costs 39 Table 2 Data Sources 52 Table 3 List of countries 55 Table 4 Industries and their institutional intensities 57 Table 5 Summary Statistics of Internet Hosts by Country 59 Table 6 Results of OLS Estimation 62 Table 7 Results of Panel Data Estimation 65 Table A.1 321 Wood Products 76 Table A.2 336 Transportation Equipment 77 Table A.3 313 Textiles and Fabrics 78 Table A.4 323 Printed Matter and Related Products 79 Table A.5 326 Plastics and Rubber Products 80 Table A.6 324 Petroleum and Coal Products 81 Table A.7 322 Paper 82 Table A.8 211 Oil and Gas 83 Table A.9 511 Newspaper 84 vi     Table A.10 327 Nonmetallic Minerals 85 Table A.11 333 Machinery 86 Table A.12 112 Livestock and Livestock Products 87 Table A.13 316 Leather & Allied Products 88 Table A.14 337 Furniture and Fixtures 89 Table A.15 311 Food and Kindred Products 90 Table A.16 114 Fish, Fresh/chilled/Frozen and Other Marine Products 91 Table A.17 332 Fabricated Metal Products 92 Table A.18 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components 93 Table A.19 334 Computer and Electronic Products 94 Table A.20 312 Beverages & Tobacco Products 95 Table A.21 315 Apparel and Accessories 96 Table A.22 111 Agricultural Products 97 Table B.1 324 Petroleum and Coal Industry 98 Table B.2 111 Agriculture Products 99 Table B.3 315 Apparel and Accessories Industry 100 Table B.4 312 Beverage and Tobacco Products 101 vii     Table B.5 325 Chemical Industry 102 Table B.6 334 Computer and Electronics Industry 103 Table B.7 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances and Components 104 Table B.8 332 Fabricated Metal Products 105 Table B.9 114 Fish and Marine Industry 106 Table B.10 311 Food and Kindred Industry 107 Table B.11 113 Forestry Products Industry 108 Table B.12 337 Furniture and Fixtures 109 Table B.13 316 Leather and Allied Products Industry 110 Table B.14 112 Livestock Industry 111 Table B.15 333 Machinery Industry 112 Table B.16 327 Nonmetallic Mineral Products 113 Table B.17 511 Newspaper Industry 114 Table B.18 211 Oil and Gas Industry 115 Table B.19 322 Paper Industry 116 Table B.20 326 Plastics Industry 117 Table B.21 323 Printed Matter and Related Products 118 viii     Table B.22 313 Textile Industry 119 Table B.23 336 Transportation Industry 120 Table B.24 321 Wood Industry 121 Table B.25 212 Minerals and Ore 122 Table C.1 111 Agriculture Basic Statistics 123 Table C.2 111 Agriculture Correlation and Covariances 124 Table C.3 112 Livestock & Livestock Products Basic Statistics 125 Table C.4 112 Livestock & Livestock Products Correlations and Covariance 126 Table C.5 114 Fish, Fresh/Chilled/Frozen and Other Marine Basic Statistics 127 Table C.6 114 Fish, Fresh/Chilled/Frozen and Other Marine Correlations and Covariances 128 Table C.7 211 Oil and Gas Basic Statistics 129 Table C.8 211 Oil and Gas Correlations and Covariance 130 Table C.9 311 Food and Kindred Products Basic Statistics 131 Table C.10 311 Food and Kindred Products Correlations and Covariances 132 Table C.11 312 Beverages and Tobacco Products Basic Statistics 133 Table C.12 312 Beverages and Tobacco Products Correlations and Covariances 134 Table C.13 313 Textiles and Fabrics Basic Statistics 135 ix     Table C.14 313 Textiles and Fabrics Correlations and Covariances 136 Table C.15 315 Apparel and Accessories Basic Statistics 137 Table C.16 315 Apparel and Accessories Correlations and Covariances 138 Table C.17 316 Leather and Allied Products Basic Statistics 139 Table C.18 316 Leather and Allied Products Correlations and Covariances 140 Table C.19 321 Wood Products Basic Statistics 141 Table C.20 321 Wood Products Correlations and Covariances 142 Table C.21 322 Paper Basic Statistics 143 Table C.22 322 Paper Correlations and Covariances 144 Table C.23 323 Printed Matter and Related Products Basic Statistics 145 Table C.24 323 Printed Matter and Related Products Correlations and Covariances 146 Table C.25 324 Petroleum and Coal Products Basic Statistics 147 Table C.26 324 Petroleum and Coal Products Correlations and Covariances 148 Table C.27 326 Plastic & Rubber Products Basic Statistics 149 Table C.28 326 Plastic & Rubber Products Correlations and Covariances 150 Table C.29 327 Non Metallic Mineral Ores Basic Statistics 151 Table C.30 327 Non Metallic Mineral Ores Correlations and Covariances 152 x     Table C.31 332 Fabricated Metal Products Basic Statistics 153 Table C.32 332 Fabricated Metal Products Correlations and Covariances 154 Table C.33 333 Machinery, Except Electrical Basic Statistics 155 Table C.34 333 Machinery, Except Electrical Correlations and Covariances 156 Table C.35 334 Computer and Electronic Products Basic Statistics 157 Table C.36 334 Computer and Electronic Products Correlations and Covariances 158 Table C.37 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components Basic Statistics 159 Table C.38 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Comps Correlations and Covariances 160 Table C.39 336 Transportation Equipment Basic Statistics 161 Table C.40 336 Transportation Equipment Correlations and Covariances 162 Table C.41 337 Furniture and Fixtures Basic Statistics 163 Table C.42 337 Furniture and Fixtures Correlations and Covariances 164 Table C.43 511 Newspapers, Books & Other Published Matter Basic Statistics 165 Table C.44 511 Newspapers, Books & Other Published Matter Correlations and Covariances 166 xi     LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1 Impact of Broadband on bilateral trade at an industry level 39 Figure 2 OLS Estimate vs. Industry Institutional Intensities 65 Figure 3 Panel Estimates vs. Industry Institutional Intensities 65 xii     1. INTRODUCTION Over the last few decades, Internet and telecommunication technologies have been adopted across the globe. Unlike other technology revolutions, this growth has been visible not only in high income countries but also in developing and lower income nations. This large scale growth in communication across the globe has had multi-faceted impacts. Information and communication technologies have influenced interpersonal communications, social interactions, and are transforming economic activities at local, national and international levels. ICTs affect business transactions in several ways. On an international level, information and communication technology can possibly have an impact on market-driven activities (international trade), activities that involve a more hierarchical structure of governance (some foreign direct investments, multinational corporations etc.) and activities that are more contractual in nature (licensing agreements etc.). The above mentioned kinds of economic structures are different in their coordination structures and hence have different costs and risks involved. The impact of information and communication technology on these cross-border economic activities varies with the differences in their respective organizational structure, cost structures and risks. ICT benefits market-driven activities like international trade that are potentially affected by problems of asymmetric information by reducing search costs and basic logistics of trade are easier to monitor with the use of these technologies. More hierarchical organizations like multinational corporations have a more complex structure and require a higher level of coordination. These hierarchical economic activities typically also exhibit a high degree of asset specificity that might require large investments. ICTs have multiple affordances that improve coordination and transfer of information within these organizations. Use of video conferencing, 1     centralized information networks and other such applications within these organizations have hugely reduced costs and improved efficiencies. Contractual economic relations, such as licensing agreements, are typically less complex, but there are certain information asymmetries that could result in poorer decisions about the licensing agreement. The use of ICT has also led to a more awareness about cultures around the world. There is more information about different kinds of markets making the global market more accessible to most countries. These are a few of the many ways in which ICT can help reduce information asymmetries and improve decision making. This study however, focuses only on the impact of these information and communication technologies on the market-driven activity of international trade. While there are several studies that look at the impact of the Internet on international trade (Freund and Weinhold 2000, 2002, 2004; Berthelon and Freund 2008), this is a first attempt to understand the impact of information and communication technologies on international trade in different industrial sectors with varying levels of relationship-specific investments. A measure of the level of relationship-specific investments in a particular industry was constructed by Nunn (2007) and is termed “contract intensity” of that particular sector. In other studies such as Levchenko (2011), contract intensity is also called “institutional intensity” of an industrial sector, defined as the dependence of that particular industrial sector on relationship-specific investments and contracts. Traditionally, countries with better institutional quality have a comparative advantage with respect to industries that involve relationship-specific investments and contracts (Levchenko 2004, Antras 2007, Acemoglu et al. 2005, Costinot 2005). The institutional dimension that is of interest in this scenario is the quality of contract enforcement in a country. In the literature, there are several variables that have been used as indicators of the quality of 2     contract enforcement in a country. These include the “regulatory quality index” calculated by the World Bank (2004) and the “rule of law” from Kaufmann, Kraay and Mastruzzi (2003). This study examines the effect of information and communication technologies on different industries to analyze if these technologies have changed the trends in trade in more institutionally intensive industries. While it is difficult to dispute that information and communication technology has had some role to play in the way international trade has changed over time, this study attempts to analyze whether the Internet influences institutionally intensive industrial sectors (investments in these industries are relationship specific) more than other sectors (sectors where investments are not as relationship specific), thereby indicating a reduction in transaction and information cost associated with institutionally intensive industries. Countries that have good institutional arrangements (better regulatory quality or better systems to enforce contractual obligations) had an advantage while trading in such institutionally intensive industries. Reduction of transaction costs not only benefits countries that have poorer institutional arrangements but also benefits countries that already have higher institutional quality by improving coordination and information transfer. Internet and communication technologies have an impact on most kinds of economic activities as they usually act as enablers of communication between individuals and organizations, including those in different countries. Information and communication technologies enable information acquisition, market access, export promotion and efficient coordination. Costs associated with these activities have been identified as important impediments to international trade between two countries in a particular industry (Samiee and Walters, 1990 and Samiee 1998). Besides being able to reduce information asymmetries and transaction costs of these economic activities explicitly, Internet and communication 3     technologies could lead to better awareness of national cultures and this could lead to more global cultural integration or fragmentation in some cases. In an organizational context, greater integration has frequently been linked to greater firm performance (Barney 1991, Chalmeta et al.. 2001). Hence, we expect that the integration enabled by Internet and communication technologies would also impact the overall production of the country and hence have a positive impact on its international trade. This study explores the role of information and communication technology in trade by reducing information asymmetries and transaction costs especially in industries that require relationship-specific investments. However, these technologies may also help highly competitive, but institutionally less intensive industries by reducing search costs and enabling better coordination. Since 1980, the world has seen a disproportionate rise in trade volumes as compared to the increase in world real GDP (Berthelon and Freund 2008). New industries have come into existence and new trading partnerships are being entered into all over the world. It is possible that some of the factors that were traditionally responsible for facilitating better trade between some countries are now affected by the use of information and communication technology. The deluge of technical features in current-day technology is capable of impacting not only economic costs, but also cultural factors that traditionally played a role in international trade. This study explores if broadband access influences bilateral trade flows in more institutionally intensive sectors more heavily than others. Better institutional quality of a country has been important for those countries trading in institutionally intensive sectors as these institutions by themselves are a critical factor in increasing the country’s comparative advantage in that sector (Levchenko 2007, Nunn 2007). Better institutions enable more reliable transactions and lower coordination costs. 4     This study proposes that the availability of broadband technology in the last decade may have also played an important role in changing trends in bilateral trade by reducing certain costs associated with it. Costs associated with trade are broadly categorized as production costs, coordination costs (distance related and others) and information costs. Different industries are characterized by varying levels of these costs; hence one could hypothesize that the different affordances of the Internet have varying effects on trade in different industries. It is of interest to take a closer look and examine some whether certain sectors affected by the use of the technology more than others. Different sectors also have different levels of institutional intensity, and some manage to mitigate a significant amount of their production and transaction costs by adopting information and communication technologies. In other words, this study is interested in exploring if the adoption of information and communication technologies affects certain industry sectors more than others? This study is a first of its kind to analyze the impact of Internet technologies on trade particularly on industrial sectors that have a high institutional intensity. The impact of institutions on trade has been studied before (McLaren 2000, Grossman and Helpman 2002, 2003, 2005, Levchenko 2004, Antras 2005, Acemoglu et al. 2005, Costinot 2005), but this is a first study that looks at how the use of Internet technology affects trade, with a particular emphasis on institutionally intensive sectors. It is interesting to investigate whether the Internet enhances the existing institutional arrangements in countries that are known to have good institutional arrangements, and further if the technology is able to provide some affordances of good institutions in those countries that lack these arrangements. In other words, it is intriguing to explore whether Internet technology is able to provide similar institutional affordances to 5     countries that lack a high quality of contract enforcement, and give them a chance to compete in trade sectors that are more contractually intensive. One motivation for this study is to examine whether the use of Internet affects trading firms in those countries where the government is rather sluggish in improving overall institutional arrangements along with influencing those countries that already have these arrangements in place. It must be kept in mind that the Internet benefits trade in multiple ways and could potentially also benefit sectors that are not institutionally intensive, especially sectors that are highly competitive. The main contribution of this study is that it gives us an understanding of how Internet affects bilateral trade in different sectors by impacting the underlying costs in these sectors. This industry wise break up according to institutional intensities provides us with some insight into what sectors that benefit from the use of Internet technology in trade and why. Empirically, the dissertation analyzes the effect of broadband technology on bilateral trade in the US between 2002 and 2010. The study includes 22 industries characterized by different institutional intensities Nunn (2007). The study uses the traditional international trade gravity equation which is essentially designed around the concept that a country is more likely to trade with another country that is physically closer and larger, than a country that is smaller and further away. In this study, the gravity equation is modified to account for other factors important to trade including the size of the information and communication sector of the respective trading countries. The study finds evidence that the use of ICT positively affects both sectors with high and low institutional intensity. The use of the technology plays a role in reducing transaction costs and production costs. Findings from this study have important policy implications for the use of 6     Internet technology for firms in countries with poorer institutional arrangements. Broadband Internet access increases their ability to compete in sectors that they traditionally had a disadvantage in. This study also has important policy implications for the use of Internet technology in industries that tend to be highly competitive in nature. The next section of the dissertation will review the existing literature in this area of research. The following two sections provide a conceptual framework for the study as well as define the methodological approach. The final two sections look at the empirical evidence and its policy implications. 7     2. LITERATURE REVIEW This dissertation studies the impact on overall bilateral trade flows as a result of technology adoption and use. It is interesting to study the effect of information and communication technologies on specific sectors or economic activities, and evaluate whom these technologies have benefited. This can also inform us on whether and how countries and industries should use these technologies to improve coordination, reduce risk and gain information in this highly interconnected and globalized world. Even in trade, it is possible that some countries benefit more than some others by using the technology because of the inherent nature of industries that they invest in or because of the existence of other country level factors (or lack of complementary resources) that make the adoption and efficient use of the technology difficult. In this section, we review literature that has investigated the economic impact of ICT. In the first section, we examine the broader literature that addresses the impact of ICT on overall economic productivity, which has repercussions for trade. In the next section, we narrow down to and review the literature that addresses the impact of ICT on one specific economic activity “trade”. Broader findings that apply to the overall impact on economic productivity also apply to trade. Besides economic productivity, ICT also additionally impacts another important factor influencing trade called “transaction costs” (discussed in the third section). Finally, the last section highlights contributions of this dissertation and the motivations derived from past literature. 8     2.1 Internet and Communication Technology and Economic Productivity Since the coining of the term “Solow’s paradox” in which Robert Solow argued that you can see the computer everywhere except in productivity statistics, there have been several studies that have made an attempt to explain this observation. Solow’s paradox was coined because a key finding was that since 1973 the residual economic growth had slowed down just when IT investments had risen. Residual growth is the spillover after growth of all inputs is taken into account (Robert Solow 1957). Several studies including Brynjolfsson and Yang (1996) did not find a correlation between IT and productivity. They largely attributed this to lack of data and inability of analytical methodologies to capture the impact quantitatively. A recent study by Forman et al. (2010) found evidence for increasing wage inequality with the adoption of the Internet. However the paradox was largely demystified when scholars like Brynjolfsson looked into the reasons for the paradox and found them to be associated with measurement errors, lags in productivity and the lack of accountability of quality and variety changes brought about by these technologies. Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2000) find that complementary investments in institutions are required for benefits from IT investments to be fully realized. Other studies have tried to explain the reason for this paradox by defining conditions under which productivity is most likely to increase (Hughes and Morton 2005). Some studies find that the impact of information technology depends on the availability of complementary resources. Some scholars (Brynjolfsson and Hitt 2000 and Draca et al. 2006) find that traditional studies confirming Solow’s paradox do not account for the existence of these complementary resources. Others (Dedrick 2003) refuted the productivity paradox in both firm level and country level studies and explained that complementary investments accounted for 9     difference between organizations. This was supported in some studies (Melville 2004) that also find that the impact of IT investments depends on the level of complementary environment.   Complementary environment refers to other changes in organizational structure that make work environment more conducive to the use of IT (e.g. adequate worker training in IT). Some studies (Bresnahan and Trajtenberg 1995) advocated the idea that information and communication technology had some impact on productivity when they used a transaction cost perspective to discuss how general purposes technologies can act as ‘engines of growth’. Similarly, some (Hubbard 2003) explored how Internet and other ICT products help increase productivity by improving the matching process between people and products. While some other scholars like Athey and Stern (2000) studied productivity effects in specific industries (in this study the researchers looked at how information technology impacts the health care industry in specific). The above studies find that the productivity paradox was largely a result of empirical limitations, but in some cases the benefits of the technology were not realized because of a lack of complementary investments that are required to make the most of the technology. Van Aek and Inklaar (2005) find the impact of ICT on productivity is also time dependent as countries and economies take time to realize the benefits of the technology and adapt accordingly. Similarly, they find that different economic sectors benefit from the technology differently because of the inherent characteristics of the different sectors. Despite the typical endogeneity challenges that are involved in measuring the impact of technology on productivity, Crandall, Lehr and Litan (2007) find sufficient evidence that ICTs do impact productivity growth. A literature review of broadband’ s impact on productivity (Holt and Jamison 2009, Kretschmer 2012) found that the technology had a positive impact on various productivity indicators, but it was hard to measure 10     the impact of the technology with precision because of endogeneity issues that studies like these typically tend to have. While it is difficult to evaluate the overall welfare gains from the use of information and communication technology, what we understand from previous literature is that the technology may help reduce costs in some sectors and increase productivity in some industrial sectors more than in others. While the use of information and communication technologies may result in net gains for consumers and some industrial sectors, there may be some sectors that for several reasons are unable to use the technology effectively for their benefit. In a literature review about firm-level productivity effects, Pilat (2004) explores the different factors/ complementary resources that need to be considered while studying the impact of ICT on industry level impact. The factors that impact ICT at a firm level help understand why some sectors and some countries perform better with ICT investments. It depends on the level of ICT related skills that already exist and if they don’t exist the technology takes longer to have an impact. The impact of ICT also depends on several organizational factors like the amount of training provided, the firm’s experience with innovation and its use if advanced business practices and the restricting of the organization that should accompany ICT use for its benefits to be realized. There is also some correlation between the size and age of a firm on how it utilizes ICT to improve productivity. Larger and newer firms tend to use the technology better and hence see greater benefits. This firm level analysis does aggregate to overall impacts on the economy. Gretton et al. (2004) find considerable impacts of ICT while using firm level data in Australia. Hampell et al. (2004), Arvanitis (2004), Baldwin (2004) find that labor productivity increases are correlated with ICT use in German, Dutch, Swiss and Canadian firms. The above studies capture how these technologies have not only been able to cut down some transaction costs and 11     information costs at the firm and industry level, but they have also created new markets and products. 12     2.2 ICT and its Effect on Trade One area where information and communication technologies should have significant impact on productivity is trade. Internet and communication technology can affect trade by acting as an economic enabler as well as by integrating the country socially, economically and culturally with the rest of the world. Internet and communication technology can act as economic enabler in two possible manners. Information and communication technology have the ability to reduce transaction costs in trade, further Internet technology has also been rather successful in creating new opportunities that did not exist before. While both trade in goods and services are impacted by the availability of Internet and communication technologies, one must note that trade in goods is impacted largely by the reduction of non-distance related co-ordination and information costs. For example, some products have huge transportation costs that comprise a major chunk of their overall costs, and those costs probably cannot be substantially mitigated by ICT. ICT could improve the logistics involved in the transportation process in order to ensure that perishables and other time sensitive goods are delivered in time, but the actual costs of transportation still continue to exist. Hence some distance related costs are mitigated because of increased coordination and reduced transaction costs, but the cost of fuel and the actual transportation process are not impacted by the technology. Trade in services just like trade in goods benefits from the lower transaction and information costs that Internet technology enables, but there is a bigger impact of information and communication technology on the trade of services because it can mitigate distance effects in some sectors completely and make services more tradable (although legal restrictions also have an impact). Internet technology adoption results in the creation of new opportunities because temporal and location boundaries now cease to exist because of the unique properties of the new 13     technology (Freund and Weinhold 2002). Some studies (Choi 2010) have found that access to the Internet almost doubles the trade in services. The widespread use of the technology has also given rise to a new class of jobs requiring the skills to set up, maintain, upgrade, modify and innovate different uses of the technology itself. Freund and Weinhold (2000) studied Internet technology specifically and found the following: first, trade benefits from information and communication technology because the risk of sunk costs associated with trade can be largely reduced. This is because the use of information and communication technology results in better information and co-ordination of the trade process. For products that involve relationship-specific investments, informed decision making reduces the risk of these investments as the trading parties involved are better informed about each other’s expectations, and the co-ordination process involved in the supply chain is more regulated. They also found that for developing and new markets, Internet technology reduces the effect of historical linkages because better communication enables higher levels of trust and mutual understanding of the environment of business and partnership. They found that countries with the fewest past trade linkages (most likely the poor countries) have the most to gain from the Internet as it gives them the opportunity to build new relationships and develop new industries. If these countries had competitive advantages in particular industries but were unable to enter the market because of historical linkages, the information and communication technology provides them with tools to establish a trade relationship that is characterized by a higher level of information and co-ordination. Several scholars have investigated further, and have found unique trends in trade when access to internet is increased. Clarke and Wallsten (2010) found that increases in internet access in developing countries increases trade but only exports to other developed countries. The 14     widespread use of Internet technology does create some winners and some losers in the process. Countries that do not use the technology effectively to improve their processes are rendered more vulnerable. Similarly, countries that earlier benefited because of historical linkages may now have to face more competition. Countries that have some competitive disadvantage but could still trade with neighboring countries will now find it harder to find a market for their products. There are several studies that have looked at the effect of ICT in specific countries or regions (Dimelis and Papaioannou 2011, Martinez 2003, Rana 2012, Wong Pellan 2012). There are several studies that have studied the impact of ICT on a variety of outcomes including the effect on trade secrets (Majdali 2000), international conflicts (Mansfield and Pollins 2009), polarization of skills demand (Van Reenan 2012) and impact on culture (Affortunato et al 2013). Some studies in the past have looked at the effect of Internet on specific industries like health care, food and beverage and so on (Fleming 2011, Chung et al 2010, Corso and Gastaldi 2010). Whatever, the scenario it is likely that information and communication technologies have changed some trading patterns. While there have been studies showing impact of trade on particular countries/regions, particular outcomes and particular industries, this study is the first one to analyze the impact of internet on bilateral trade on a list of industries specified by their institution intensities. In other words, we are particularly interested in the effect of Internet technology on trade to analyze if industries with high relationship-specific needs are impacted in any way. These industries traditionally tend to be very risky and there is a significant amount of trust involved in these trade relationships. It is possible that some of these industries are directly related to the ICT sector and their productivity is directly impacted by ICT investments and use. However, this study attempts to also include other relationship specific manufacturing and agricultural sectors 15     in the sample to analyze if there is also a reduction in contractual transaction and information costs. 16     2.3 Transaction Costs and the Importance of Institutions The concept of transaction cost was introduced by Ronald Coase (1937) who discussed why it was not efficient for all exchanges to be organized as markets and how firms played an important role in enabling exchanges and improving transactions. The argument was further elaborated by Williamson (1975, 1985) when he specified why transaction costs exist and what were the risks involved when transaction costs were high. The overall argument was that transaction costs existed because human beings were limited with respect to knowledge, foresight, skill and time. Certain institutional arrangements were required in order to avoid incomplete contracts and enable exchanges that would have been impossible otherwise. He goes on to state that there are essentially two types of risks involved in carrying out any exchange. One is relational risk that arises because of information asymmetries, limited foresight, lack of skills, cognitive abilities and even purely from coordination problems that arise because of communication issues. The next type of risk is environmental risk and does not pertain to the relationship between the two parties but exists because people have very limited knowledge about their environment as well as the environment of the party they are conducting business with. For example, people may not be aware of policy changes made by the government in their own country leave alone the country of the other business party involved. Institutions are particularly important in industries that require relationship-specific investments and contracts. Several studies have depicted the importance of contract enforcement in these industries (Williamson 1985, Grossman and Hart (1986) and Klien, Crawford and Alchian 1978). The incomplete contracts literature shows that the absence of proper institutional arrangements could potentially lead to a well-known hold-up problem. Since investments in relationship specific contracts involve investments that are specific to the contract, there exist certain inefficiencies because of investment irreversibility. Parties often have to enter into 17     elaborate contracts that prevent hold up problems or at least distribute the losses due to hold up problems by assigning appropriate property rights. Hence institutional arrangements become rather important in such industries and particularly in international trade. Levchenko (2008) states that institutions are a source of comparative advantage in industries that are more relationship-specific. Some countries have better institutions and are therefore able to attract more business in more relationship specific sectors. It is possible that the Internet could play an important role in reducing the importance of these institutional arrangements in more relationship specific or institutionally intensive sectors. Keeping the basics of transaction cost theory, it is evident that ICT can reduce the burden from traditional institutions in a country that often play a critical role in reducing transaction costs in an international market exchange. Given the nature of ICT there is no doubt that it certainly has properties that reduces information asymmetries, improves coordination efforts, enables the provision of better communication technology at a very low marginal cost and transcends the boundaries of time and location to reduce transaction costs significantly. Both environmental and relational risks are significantly lowered with the use of Internet technology, which therefore should have a positive effect on exchanges that take place across boundaries. As discussed earlier, there is rich economic literature that has shown that there is a significant gain in productivity from the use of Internet technology. Hubbard (2003) discusses how Internet and other ICT products help increase productivity by improving the matching process between people and products. In today’s world where there is so much variety within and across nations. Internet and communication technology brings the most closely matching products to the buyer thereby leading to a productivity gain. The faster and easier search process results in inventory savings as well. The existence of various directories and search engines and 18     communication technologies gives opportunities to the less established exporters to gain information about market conditions. Hamill and Gregory (1997), Hoffman and Novak (1996), and Athey and Stern (2002) look at how information technology impacts the health care industry in specific. They look at lower transaction costs that have been achieved by the use of Internet technology because of an improvement in the speed of processing information. The speeding up of processes can reduce opportunity costs of both time and material by reducing market uncertainties. They find that in the medical industry prevention of lagged information produced economic gains that covered 85% of their costs. Paul David (1990) refers to the same thing in terms of ‘amenities’ provided by technology. In his paper, he goes on to look at the problem of productivity paradox that might arise because of the use of a new technology. This is particularly relevant to our study as we do not know whether Internet technology actually leads to productivity gains in trade in all sectors equally, or if only some sectors that are inherently capable of restructuring their businesses to use the technology most efficiently benefit. In this respect Chun et al. (2005) uses Schumpeter’s creative destruction approach to explain how newer competitive firms use Internet and other information technologies to make more established firms obsolete. Even a non-exporting firm can enter the market in some industries if it is able to use the Internet and create a website to reach out to buyers in different parts of the world thereby creating a competitive advantage itself (Samiee 1998). It is also possible that some industries might end up exporting lesser because ICT improves search within a country and an exporting firm might end up supply more domestically and a non-exporting firm might find more business in its own country. From the above literature it is clear that Internet and communication technologies may be useful in reducing transaction costs provided, some other basic economic and technological 19     factors are taken care off. This is true particularly in the case of services where Internet technology not only lowers transaction costs but also creates new opportunities by transcending temporal and location boundaries (Freund and Weinhold 2002). In order for Internet and communication technologies to have a positive impact on trade, it is essential that the competitive advantage that ICT technology gives to some countries is larger than the competitive disadvantage that some trading nations(either because their ICT usage is low or because of increased competition) may now face (Samiee 1998). Secondly, even though the Internet and communication technologies might enable easier transactions, trade is possible only if a country decides to open its legal and regulatory framework to allow for these kinds of exchanges. Thirdly, technological misuse like intellectual property violation or lack or privacy or security could further cause impediments to trade and leading to higher transaction costs. Fourthly, it is important to keep in mind that the proper adoption and use of the technology is possible only if some basic socio-economic factors are taken into consideration and this may play an important role in which countries benefit by the use of the technology in trade (Benjamin and Wiegand, 1995; Hoffman and Novak, 1996; Quelch and Klein, 1996). Under the right set of conditions, information and communication technologies can benefit both exporters and importers by lowering their firm level co-ordination costs, reducing risks involved in international trade by enabling better information flows, by helping some industries be more productive because of overall lower costs and by reducing cultural distance between countries. It is also possible that some industries that are not capable of restructuring in order to use the technology more effectively, may not see any changes. Additionally some industries with higher transportation costs might just end up finding suppliers domestically thereby reducing demand for exports. 20     2.4 Research Questions and Contributions of this Study In this study, an attempt is made to use organizational communication literature as well as transaction cost theory to understand the mechanism by which information and communication technology (particularly the Internet) can benefit trade in some industrial sectors more than others. This study looks at how certain kinds of information and transaction cost in different industry sectors are reduced with the use of certain information and communication technologies, whereas certain other kinds of costs are not affected by information and communication technologies. A de-compositional framework is used that examines how affordances like audibility, visibility, co-presence, mobility, co-temporality, co-presence, reviewability and revisability affect the important collaborative tasks of initiating conversation, establishing common ground, and maintaining awareness of potentially relevant changes in the collaborative trade environment. These affordances are beneficial in varying degrees to different industrial sectors. A conceptual framework is developed to understand the contribution of the Internet in different industrial sectors that are largely classified by the degree relationship specific investments involved. While the reasons for the impact of Internet on trade in different sectors maybe difficult to test empirically, the conceptual framework will provide us with some understanding of the varying trends in different industries. The main research question explored in this dissertation is how information and communication technologies have impacted international trade flows in sectors that have varying levels of relationship-specific investments. Do arguments of increased productivity due to ICT also hold for international trade in some sectors? Different industries have inherent characteristics that have varying levels of benefits from using the different of information and communication technologies. Industries can be classified by the nature of investments made in them. One particular kind of investment that involves high levels of transaction costs are 21     relationship specific investments. Industries with higher levels of such investments require better institutional arrangements to avoid hold up problems (Levchenko 2008). Does the Internet or broadband technology provide some sort of alternative arrangements that reduce transaction and information costs? A detailed study of the different industries between 2002 and 2010 can shed light on which industries have benefited the most by the use of broadband technologies and hence what the policy implications for different trading nations are. 22     3. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK Information and communication technologies influence trade through their impact on multiple levels of economic activity. These technologies have an effect on productivity on a more aggregate industry and national level through their impact on the productivity at an individual firm level. Furthermore, information and communication technologies have an impact on trade because of its overall impact on transaction costs involved in trade. The following subsections are set up in the following manner. In the first subsection, technical affordances of the technology are discussed. Identifying these affordances is crucial in understanding how the technology impacts trade costs (transaction and production), and this impact on trade costs is discussed in the next subsection. The following subsection then goes into a discussion of institutional arrangements and how technology impacts trade in different industries through its impact on these institutional arrangements. In the final subsection, the overall framework is developed by understanding the relationship between the technological affordances that broadband provides and the factors that drive bilateral trade in different industries. Controlling for the other factors that play a major role in bilateral trade, a conceptual framework is developed to predict the relationship between broadband technology and trade in specific industrial sectors characterized by their relationship specific investments. 23     3.1 Affordances of Internet (Broadband Technology) The Internet and in particular broadband technology has different technological affordances that can help mitigate costs involved in bilateral trade in different ways. Based on a study by (Clark and Brennan 1991 and Kraut el al 2002) the technological affordances of information and communication technologies are described in Table 1. The first one is ‘audibility’ where the participants can hear people and the sounds of an environment. This enables quicker co-ordination as it allows for a simultaneous conversation to take place, doubts and questions can be immediately addressed and there is a slightly higher awareness about the general environmental and relational risks involved. The next affordance that is discussed is ‘visibility’, and this allows participants to view people and objects in the environment. The Internet is the only information and communications technology with this affordance as it enables one to see pictures, or chat live via video chatting services online and review documents and emails. Thirdly, Internet technology enables interacting entities to experience ‘co-presence’, and this essentially allows participants to be mutually aware that they share an environment. This affordance is slightly more difficult to comprehend in the context of trade, but can be interpreted as the ability of both trading partners to understand the physical environment in which they are carrying out the activity. Broadband Internet is able to offer this affordance at the highest level by enabling tracking of a product, performing quality check and so on by allowing for frequent conversations, exchange of documents and instantaneous updates on the status a delivery or production. The fourth affordance is ‘mobility’, which is a feature that enables participants to move around while sharing an environment (or exchanging information about it). Broadband Internet is becoming relatively more mobile these days with the availability 24     of wireless service everywhere, and the ability of participants to access information from any computer that is connected to network service provider. ‘Co-temporality’ is an affordance that enables participants to be present simultaneously. This affordance is offered by broadband Internet to some degree, but requires individuals to use applications online that are specifically designed for this purpose. ‘Reviewability’ is an affordance that ensures that messages do not fade over time and can be reviewed at any time. Internet allows for this affordance at the highest level as documents can be exchanged between the two trading parties in short amounts of time. The final affordance that we are interested in is ‘revisability’, which essentially allows for messages to be revised or checked before being sent. Broadband Internet allows for revisability depending on the Internet application used, because the nature of most voice/video services requires conversations to be instantaneous, hence making ‘revisability’ more difficult while using those mediums of communication that instantaneously transfer voice and video messages. However, there exist several video and voice applications that only host visual and verbal messages that are pre-recorded and such applications do allow for ‘revisability’. Besides having these technological affordances it should be noted that broadband technology has changed over the past decade contributing to a large extent on the effect that they have on international trade. According to Clemons et al. (1993), the ways in which ICT usually change over time is the following: a. Decreasing cost of the technology: In the past decade markets have witnessed significant drop in the cost of broadband access. The falling cost of the service will result in these technologies having a bigger influence on trade over time. 25     b. Improved quality of the technology: The quality of broadband technology has changed over time thereby changing their technical affordances. While analyzing data over time it is important to keep in mind the additional and improved affordances offered by these technologies. For example, the mobile phone migrated from 2G to 3G and now to 4G and mobile Internet is widely used all over the world; information technology has seen increased processing capacity, better speeds of computer hardware, higher bandwidths, Internet speeds and larger number of applications being developed for the web. These changes need to be considered while understanding the influence of Internet technology over time. c. Better connectivity and standardization: Open systems, standardized hardware etc. enable better coordination and dissemination of information. These changes have occurred because of technological improvements as well as policy changes. These changes are very important in enabling the use of broadband technology efficiently across countries and hence have had an impact on how they influenced international trade. d. Growing number of applications: Not only has broadband infrastructure access and service improved over the last decade, but the number of applications that are developed and hosted over the network has exponentially grown. The growth of these applications have created added value for the network itself, and has given rise to huge network benefits (e.g. more peer to peer collaborations, use in government transactions) that impact economic activities all around the world. In the following subsections we will discuss how these technological affordances impact trade by impacting transaction costs involved in trade and overall aggregate productivity at the industry level. 26     3.2 ICT and its Impact on Trade Costs It is important that before we begin our discussion on ICT and its impact on international trade, we briefly discuss highlights of existing theories of international trade. The existing trade theories can be divided into two main groups. The first group assumes perfect competition and suggests that external economies of scale are the biggest driver of international trade. This group of trade theories generally makes an assumption that goods and services produced by a country is dependent on factors that are very country/region specific. Trade theories that fall into this group are Adam Smith’s model of absolute advantage (Adam Smith 1776), the Ricardian model of comparative advantage, and finally the Heckscher-Ohlin model that states that international trade is determined differences in factor endowments. The second group consists of scholars that looked into the concept of imperfect competition and internal economies of scale. This was largely known as the new trade theory and demonstrated that countries trade with each other even when there is no perfect competition or specialization. This is because consumers like choice and consider varieties of the same product substitutable. Krugman (1980) and Helpman and Krugman (1985) found that firms produce a variety of goods with increasing returns to scale technology. This phenomenon was particularly helpful in explaining why two similar developed countries enter into trade. ICT in particular impacts both internal and external economies of scale by reducing production and transaction costs. In this study we use the gravity model derived from the Cobb Douglas expenditure system (derived from the production function) that is successful in empirically explaining trade patterns under both perfect specialization and imperfect specialization assumptions. Irrespective of whether we assume perfect competition or not, the use of the gravity equation helps empirically explain the trends in trade caused by ICT. There are different ways in which ICTs affect economic activities. ICT is capable of reducing costs in production and transaction related activities, and this influence of ICT has been 27     studied widely. Clemon et al. (1993) argue that information and communication technology because of its ability to lower coordination costs, reduces the need for more hierarchical organizational systems and one can observe that this gives rise to over-all higher economies of scale and better long term relationships between internal agents of the firm as well as external ones. The authors also find that most studies do not account for increase in quality and variety while studying productivity. Both increased quality and variety are very important to firms that want to enter the export market. They also find that for ICT to result in firm productivity, some amount of internal restructuring maybe required for a firm to fully realize all the benefits. In this section, we will discuss the impact of ICT on the transaction costs involved in an activity like international trade, as well as impact of the technology on the overall productivity of industries. Transaction costs were first discussed by Ronald Coase, and are essentially the cost of coordinating a market exchange in the presence of imperfect information. Two important aspects of transaction costs are therefore the cost of coordinating the activity and the cost of gathering information or making decisions in the presence of limited information. 28     3.2.1 Effect on Transaction Costs Bilateral trade benefits from information and communication technology because of its effects on overall transaction costs that include risks involved in the production and distribution process. Since information asymmetry is a root cause of risk that an agent has to deal with during its decision making process, this study will refer to the costs involved with better understanding and mitigating these risks as information costs. The cost of coordinating the market activity will be referred to as the coordination cost. In order to understand how these different information and communication technologies help reduce co-ordination/transaction and information costs in trade, we must understand these kinds of costs in more detail. For any agent involved in bilateral trade the overall reduction in transaction cost is the following: 1. Coordination costs: This category includes all costs that are involved in the process of carrying out the trade of the good or service between the buyer and seller or within the supplying firm. This could include logistical co-ordination costs, transportation costs and other possible costs involved in the process of trading a particular good or service. Co-ordination costs within a firm can also be lowered by ICT because use of these technologies lead to restructuring and work place re-organization that may help the firm focus on its area of core competency, increase specialization and reduce learning costs involved in the production process (Clemons et al. 1993, Bresnahan and Brynjolfsson 2002) According to a detailed study by Malone and Crowston (1991), co-ordination activities can be categorized into different co-ordination processes. The four broad categories of co-ordination processes are managing shared resources, managing producer and consumer relationships, managing simultaneity constraints and managing task/subtask relationship. Managing shared resources and tasks/subtask relationships are important activities for exporting firms because 29     they are involved in a production process that possibly uses shared resources and certainly has a certain distribution of tasks that need to be coordinated. However, these two co-ordination processes exist only for the exporting firm and are not very important in the actual market exchange involved in international trade. In the trade of goods and services, it is always the case that one partner produces a product or delivers a service without the involvement of the trading partner in the process of production. For the purpose of international trade, the two co-ordination activities that are important are managing consumer/producer relationships (in this case it is the relationship between the two trading partners) and managing simultaneity constraints, which essentially include the co-ordination of the logistics of scheduling, payment processes, transporting and so on. Malone and Crowston (1991) find that information and communication technology can reduce these co-ordination costs in the following ways 1. First-order effect of reducing coordination costs with ICT: substitution of the technology for some human coordination. For instance, many banks and insurance companies have substituted automated systems for large numbers of human clerks in their back offices. 2. Second-order effect of reducing coordination costs with ICT: Increase of the overall amount of co-ordination with the use of the technology. 3. Third-order effect of reducing coordination cost with ICT: Coordination intensive structures are set up or changed by the technology 2. Information Costs: The next category of cost that is involved in the process of carrying out the production or distribution (in this case the actual trade of a good or service) is information cost. This kind of cost arises out of information asymmetries that exist when working with someone based in a different country. These costs could be search costs or costs of finding a suitable trading partner, risks that producers may have from any asset specificity in that particular 30     industry (e.g. if a producer invests in specific machineries because they perceive a demand for the good, but they also face risks of having large sunk costs if for some reason their product goes out of demand), costs involved in finding information about the product price and quality as well as the cost of finding if there are any environmental risks involved in trading with a partner in a particular country or region. Based on the kind of industry the trade is taking place in, there are varying levels of these information costs. For example, some industries trade in products that are very country-specific and this entails added information costs about the demand of the product in the importing country. If sufficient information is not gathered about potential demand the exporting country could end up making investments on a product that cannot be exported in another market if demand falls short. Similarly, products in industries with specific environmental and health standards also require higher amount of information gathering. Some industries find it beneficial to start the process of transaction and then gather all the information that they need. This is called the transaction to information model and often takes place when the transaction costs are low. The other model is the information to transaction model and this takes place in industries where the transaction costs are significantly high, so it is beneficial to first gather information about who is the most suitable trading partner, the costs involved and the risks involved if the agreement is to be entered into. Several of these costs are reduced by the use of information and communication technologies (Levchenko 2008). Information costs are related to two categories of information asymmetry issues, namely uncertainty and equivocality (Daft, Lengel and Trevino 1987). According to these authors, uncertainty is the difference in the amount of information that is required to perform a task in the most efficient manner and the amount of information that is actually available. If the amount of information available about the task, environment and partners is low, then this creates a cost for 31     the parties involved in the transaction. Equivocality on the other hand means ambiguity of messages and this is often present when two parties present in different locations carry out a transaction. Equivocality in trade can be mitigated to a large extent by the use of appropriate information and communication technologies that have the following features of (1) providing feedback, (2) providing multiple cues in the form of voice messages, visual gestures, documents and so on (3) language variety which includes languages, pictures or numbers in conveying a message and (4) providing personal focus which enables messages to be tailored to the frame of reference, needs and current situation of the receiver. Transaction costs as described by Williamson (1979), arise from human cognitive limitations to receive, transmit and process information about the business transaction. Williamson discusses different kinds of governance structures and how they relate to transaction costs. As described earlier, this dissertation focuses on the market driven activity of trade and some inter firm transactions involved in the production process. Based on Williamson (1979, 1985), contracts are the most suitable governance structure to mitigate transaction costs in this kind of a market driven environment. This dissertation focuses on how Internet technology helps reshape the importance of this institution in particular. The affordances discussed earlier impact the different kinds of transaction costs and productivity costs to reshape the traditional institution of contracting. In this section, we have discussed the different kinds of transaction costs involved in international trade. In the next section we will briefly discuss the impact on aggregate productivity before going on to a discussion of how affordances of ICT impact overall trade costs. 32     3.2.2 ICT and its impact on aggregate productivity On an aggregate industry level, this means that broadband technology will increase overall firm productivity. It may even encourage certain new entrants to enter the market because of lower costs of coordination and information. Meltiz (2002), makes an argument for trade by saying that trade encourages the most productive firms to enter the market with the lesser productive firms producing for a domestic market. This may in the long run force less productive firms to leave the market and hence additional intra-industry reallocation of firms may take place towards more productive firms. If this argument is extended, it is possible to say that information technology further increases firm level productivity (through their impact on production, coordination and information costs as discussed earlier) and thereby results in reallocation of firms in the market to include firms that are more productive because of the use these information and communication technologies. This may have an impact at a country level because different countries have had varying degrees of success in adopting these technologies and this may affect the overall productivity of some of their industries. There may also be varying influence on different kinds of industries based on inherent industry characteristics. This may result in compositional change in bilateral trade over time, meaning that the very nature of some industries may have changed over time because of changing technology, globalization, environmental standards or other reasons that have caused industries to change significantly over time. An example of an industry that has significantly changed in nature over time is the entertainment industry. ICT has given rise to different production models for TV shows over several mediums (TV and Internet). The above discussion of aggregate productivity of an industry should be studied for different industries differently. Based on inherent industry characteristics, different industries and firms with in them can use 33     information and communication technologies with varying levels of success. Some industry characteristics that are important in this respect are the following (Levchenko 2008, Freund and Weinhold 2000, 2002, 2004). 1. Does the product involve relationship specific investment? 2. Is the product a durable or non-durable good? 3. Is there a significant transportation cost involved? Can this transportation cost be mitigated by information and communication technology and to what extent? 4. Has the nature of the product itself changed over time because of the influence on ICT? These characteristics of the industry influence the degree to which information and communication technology can be successfully used to increase productivity. Different countries because of differences in factor proportions (theory of comparative advantage) or increasing returns to scale (new trade theory), choose to invest more in certain industries and this in turn affects the degree with which they can use the technology successfully. It is possible that better adoption of information and communication technologies at a national level benefits only those countries that primarily invest in certain industrial sector like services. For example, service oriented countries with a lower adoption of these technologies may face a setback, but countries that export natural resources may not be affected by the adoption of information and communication technologies to the same extent. Increased productivity leveraged by the use of information and communication technology has an overall impact on trade because it brings down costs for the exporting country making the product cheaper. There are other theories about what impacts industry productivity in a country and what makes a country more favorable in trade. The most common theory being countries with a relative comparative advantages (or relative factor differences) in certain 34     industries are more likely to enter into trade exchanges. However, new trade theory attributes the phenomenon of trade between countries with similar skill sets without relative factor differences between them to specialization over time in certain industries due to various reasons like learning over time and so on. Irrespective of the underlying framework driving trade between the two, ICT can supplement productivity and reduce transaction costs in both scenarios. Countries that are slower to adopt and utilize the technology may be significantly impacted in a competitive global environment. ICT may potentially also create new digital products in certain industries as a direct consequence of its use in the country. It may also make some products obsolete because of the availability of new digital counterparts. Hence, ICT impacts trade between two countries because of its role in reducing transaction costs and increasing productivity. ICT may also significantly change the industry itself and might have a direct impact on the industry over time. An example of an industry that has been created by the use of ICT is the digital books industry, causing reduced demand for the traditional paper book industry. 35     3.3 Impact of ICT on Trade through its Impact on Institutional Arrangements The importance of institutions has been widely discussed in trade literature. Change in institutional arrangements is often cited as one of the most important variables influencing trade flows (Baier and Bergstrand 2001). Institutions can be described as a set of rules or explicit arrangements that authorize or prescribe certain business codes of conduct (Levchenko 2007 and Nunn 2007). They find that institutions play two major roles in trade. Institutions generate rents for some parties within the economy and are also a source of comparative advantage. Institutions according to Williamson (1985) also overcome the hold-up problem that could arise in any market exchange between two parties. Institutions are of high importance in those industrial sectors where transaction costs are high or there exist certain relationship specific investments. Transaction costs have been defined in the previous section as co-ordination and information costs involved in the trading process. Relationship specific investment is one where the production investment is unique to the relationship between the two trading parties. These kinds of investments are riskier and could result in the well-known hold up problem if it is not backed up by strong institutional arrangements (Levchenko 2008). Countries with weaker institutions could have rather incomplete contracts making international trade more risky (Caballero and Hammour 1998). Institutions could therefore end up giving certain countries a comparative advantage in certain trading sectors (Levchenko 2008). Some traditional institutions used by countries as a source of comparative advantage is better judicial quality and predictability and the enforcement of contracts in countries. As discussed earlier, broadband Internet technology has certain affordances that could reduce transactions and information costs involved in trade. By that logic the use of broadband technology should give countries trading in institutionally intense sectors 36     the similar benefits that institutional arrangements provide (E.g. better monitoring, reduced search costs). Countries that already have good institutions are further strengthened by the use of ICT, and countries that do not have good institutions now benefit from the use of broadband as it reduces certain transaction costs and uncertainties involved. As described earlier the use of ICT improves communication, allows for better and faster coordination and reduces information costs. It is possible that with the use of broadband a country that has weak institutions but significant factor differences now becomes more favorable as a trading partner. In this study, institutional intensity is sourced from Nunn (2007). Institutional intensity is the quality of a certain industry to be more dependent on institutions because of higher transaction costs involved. The higher the institutional intensity of an industry the higher the risk faced by the producing country if for some reason the exchange does not go through. The risk is higher if an industry’s inputs are tailored to very specific needs thereby making it more risky for both parties if trade is not successful. In Nunn (2007), it is defined as the fraction of each industry's inputs not sold on organized exchanges or reference priced, and is constructed based on US InputOutput Tables. Inputs that cannot be bought this way require relationship-specific investments and thus rely on good contracting institutions being in place leading to higher institutional intensity. Broadband technology can to some degree be a substitute to institutional arrangements in a particular country, though this might be empirically very difficult to show. While it improves coordination and reduces information asymmetry, it may be difficult to quantify the costs saved. In this study, we explore the possibility that broadband might have a higher impact on sectors that have high institutional intensity provided all other factors like transport costs and durability are similar. 37     3.4 Impact of Internet technology: Overall conceptual framework In this section, we will analyze the relationship between the affordances of broadband technology and their effect on international trade in different industrial sectors. Based on the affordances of broadband technology and the two kinds of costs involved in trade, the following table summarizes the effect of broadband on the costs of coordination and information. With these affordances of broadband technology taken into consideration, it can be inferred that broadband technology will have an impact on bilateral trade (in this case with the US). The use of the technology provides some sort of comparative advantage in a particular industrial sector by impacting coordination costs, information costs and improving productivity. As discussed in the previous subsections, one possible way of being a source of comparative advantage (Levchenko 2008), is by reducing transaction costs particularly in industries that are highly institutionally intensive. Institutionally intensive industries are often ones with higher information and coordination costs and therefore may benefit the most by use of ICT provided other factors remain constant (like changing nature of the industry, large transportation costs). The second way in which broadband technology can impact bilateral trade with the US is if it helps the overall productivity of a particular sector. There are some sectors that do not require relationship specific investments but still benefit from ICT because the technology can make business processes more efficient (better management and logistic processes, better record keeping, better market information and so on). These industries trade with countries because of specialization or just differences in factor proportions. These industries benefit from broadband technology simply because of increased factor productivity and lower co-ordination costs that ICT may introduce. 38     Table 1: Affordances of broadband and effect on co-ordination and information costs Technology Features/ affordances Effect on Coordination Costs Effect on Information Costs Effect on Productivity Internet Audibility, Visibility, Copresence, Cotemporality, Reviewability and Revisability 1. Managing shared nd rd resources (2 and 3 order effect in reducing costs) 2.Managing task/subtasks nd rd (2 and 3 order effect in reducing costs) 3.Managing Producer / Consumer Relationships • Improves logistics st nd rd (1 , 2 and 3 order effect in reducing costs) 4.Managing Simultaneity Constraints • Improves logistics st nd rd (1 , 2 and 3 order effect in reducing costs) • Progressive st arrangements(1 , 1.Uncertainty (information costs, monitoring costs and vulnerability costs) • High effect on reducing costs 2. Equivocality (subjective messages) • High effect on costs by reducing the risk from equivocality enabled by technology features such as i. Feedback ii. Multiple cues iii. Language iv. Personal 1.Relationship specific Investment sector • High Effect in reducing costs nd 2. Managing shared resources (2 nd rd 3 order effect in reducing costs) 4.Managing Producer / Consumer Relationships st nd • Improves logistics (1 , 2 rd and 3 order effect in reducing costs) 5.Managing Simultaneity Constraints st nd • Improves logistics (1 , 2 rd and 3 order effect in reducing costs) • Progressive arrangements st nd rd (1 , 2 and 3 order effect in reducing costs) st 6.Change in nature of industry (1 order effect that may significantly impact the industry) rd 2 and 3 order effect in reducing costs) 39     rd and 3 order effect in reducing costs) nd 3.Managing task/subtasks (2 and Finally broadband can also be instrumental in changing the nature of a particular sector (first order effect). This means that broadband technology has substituted technology for some human coordination or has changed the nature of a physical good or process of producing it. Broadband could have also increased demand of a product because of globalization and for some industries the technology may serve as a marketing tool (either directly or indirectly). The last decade has witnessed the nature of certain industries such as the entertainment industry, food and beverage industry and so on because of global information sharing that broadband technology has enabled. To summarize: broadband technology firstly reduces transaction costs in institutionally intensive sectors; secondly it also improves trading opportunities for countries that could trade with the US because of inherent differences in factor proportions by improving productivity; and finally broadband impacts trade by changing the very nature of certain industries (For example: music, books and entertainment), or could make information available more globally and increases the demand of certain products (for example: the demand for specialty food and beverage could increase because the world is more connected because of the technology). 40     Figure 1: Impact of Broadband on bilateral trade at an industry level   T&P Costs + P Costs Low II, High RCA or Specialization + or - P Costs Internet Use of Exporter High II, High RCA or Specialization Low RCA or Specialization - 41     Trade with US + or - Nature of Industry   No trade with US Other contributions (income, population, exchange rate) The above conceptual framework highlights the effect of Internet on bilateral trade with the US. Use of broadband technology could reduce both transaction costs and production costs in sectors that have higher institutional intensity (High II), Ricardian comparative advantage (where countries have factor differences causing the production of a certain good to be more efficient in the country with the relative comparative advantage thereby leading to trade between the two countries) and highly specialized trade sectors because these industries do have additional production costs because of relationship specificity that can be reduced by the use of the technology. In cases where the industry is a low institutional intensive industry, broadband technology can be still used by technologically superior countries to reduce co-ordination costs or improve search. In cases where there is no Ricardian comparative advantage (RCA) or lack of specialization, trade does not take place even with the availability of better Internet technology. The importer country (US) also can reduce its transaction costs in general by the use of this technology as it provides them with better co-ordination tools and higher information. It helps them improve their search process and identify countries with factor differences or specializations so that they can mutually benefit from international trade. Based on the above framework of reduction in costs, we infer that highly institutionally intensive industries should benefit more from the use of broadband technology. Industries with low institutional intensities also benefit from the use of the technology in bilateral trade if there are factor differences or specialization that makes trade between the two countries beneficial. Finally, broadband could have an overall impact on the industries by changing the very nature of the industry. This can happen because of multiple reasons. Firstly, broadband could give rise to a new generation of products because technology can often replace some traditional goods and services. Second, broadband is playing a big role in making the world more globalized. People 42     all over the world now have access to a huge range of information and this has changed people’s tastes and preferences for certain goods and services. In this study, we make an assessment of how Internet affects individual industries by studying how broadband has impacted trade with the largest importer in the world, the US. It may be difficult to tease out the exact nature of the impact, but the underlying framework will provide us with information about potential pathways causing these changes. Using the threedigit ISIC (International Standard Industrial Classification) Codes, we consider 25 different industries for our study. Since this study focusses on relationship-specific investments, the 25 industries were chosen such that it was easy to obtain their institutional intensities from Nunn (2007). This is discusses in more detail in the empirical evidence section. 43     3.5 Hypotheses to be Tested Based on the different possible effects of Internet use on trade costs, the following two hypotheses are proposed. H1: Internet use has a positive impact on sectors that have high institutional intensity. As discussed earlier, there is literature that suggests that institutional arrangements themselves have become a source of comparative advantage along with being able to generate rents for some agents in the industry (Levchenko 2008). As discussed earlier, relationship specific investments require better co-ordination and the minimization of information costs. Since these products are not sold in the organized market or reference priced, connections between the two trading parties are made through search processes that are largely driven by pre-existing ties and networks (Fink et al. 2002). Since these sectors are associated with a well-known risk known as the ‘hold up cost’ it was common practice to trade with countries that were known to have better institutional arrangements. The growing popularity of Internet technology especially in business largely changes this trend because the affordances of the technology can now make it possible to monitor logistics and co-ordinate more effectively to minimize risk. The presence of multiple verbal and visual cues also makes it easier to minimize risk because of better information transfer between the concerned parties. Therefore the use of Internet technology can to some degree substitute for institutional arrangements in countries where superior technology for production exists but institutional arrangements are poorer. H2: Internet use in sectors with low institutional intensity has a smaller positive impact (compared to high II sectors). This hypothesis is driven by two primary factors; a) factor differences or specialization that a country may possess; and b) the low institutional requirement of that particular industrial sector. 44     The first factor could be positively impacted by the use of broadband technology. This is because use of ICT may lead to higher overall productivity in the sector (E.g. better coordination and management, better access to information). The second factor might cause a negative impact as far as bilateral trade flows with the US is concerned (though the use of broadband might have an overall positive effect for the exporting country). This is because trade exchanges in this industry are less relationship specific and are less contractual in nature. In a lot of cases, these industries have products that are sold in the commodities market, and already have instruments in place to mitigate any transaction costs that may exist in the process of trading these products. The use of ICT may actually increase market competition and the exporting country may seek better suppliers (ones with higher demand and willingness to pay) because ICT use makes search costs lower. Let us discuss the first factor driving this hypothesis. If trade is beneficial because of existing difference in factor proportions, broadband technology can drive production costs down. Trade is often driven by factor proportion differences or by the specialization of a production process in a country over time. A country will export a product/service in sectors in which it has a cost advantage as far as factor proportions or are concerned, and will import products in sectors where the primary production factor costs are domestically very high. Since it makes sense that the difference in factor proportions will lead to trade, one must also note that countries can be rather competitive in their exports prices, and countries around the world benefit by taking measures to not only increase factor productivity, but also by improving logistics of supply. As discussed earlier, one such measure is to use Internet technology to improve factor productivity. As discussed before there are several affordances that the Internet has that make co-ordination within internal units involved in the production process easier. There is also literature that 45     supports the link between the use of ICT and improved factor productivity (Stiroh 1999, 2001 and 2002). In cases where trade happens because of specialization or increasing returns to scale, the use of broadband technology has a similar impact by increasing productivity. Hence, any exporting country benefits by the use of broadband technology as it increases productivity and reduces some transaction costs. Let us now discuss the second factor of low institutional intensity and examine how broadband technology may potentially impact bilateral trade is such industries. Low institutional intensity essentially means that countries have rather low transaction costs and products are not relationship specific. Of course, the degree of relationship specificity in every industry is different, but industries with a low institutional intensity have fewer transaction costs incurred because the product is rather generic in nature and can easily be resold in another country if trade with a particular partner does not successfully work out. Since the exporter’s product is easily sold in another country, the use of broadband technology gives the exporting country the flexibility and the information tools to carry out trade with another country that has a demand for that product. This means that the use of broadband technology by a country has opened the country up to other potential trade partners, thereby leading to a potential negative impact on bilateral trade with the US. If the exporting country has high supplies and is capable of handling multiple trading partners then it is possible that bilateral trade with the US is not negatively impacted. The extent to which this factor drives down bilateral trade between the two countries depends on several factors like the overall demand of the product globally, the exchange rates between countries, the nature of the product (durable or not) and so on. An industry that is in high demand like Oil & Gas is likely to use the technology to find other trading partners if the 46     terms of trade with the US are not favorable. The use of broadband gives them more information about the options available to them. Finally, besides these two fundamental hypotheses, it must be noted that the use of broadband technology may have pervasive impacts on some industries by changing the very nature of the product itself, or by changing tastes and preferences in a country. This study will be unable to empirically tease out the reason for these changes, but it will be able to capture an anomaly in results for industries that have been significantly impacted. It is not difficult to then attribute a cause for the anomaly by observing the general trends in those industries. 47     4. METHODOLOGY Existing literature has provided empirical evidence of the positive relationship of the Internet on international trade. This study explores if the Internet matters more in industries that are institutionally intensive. In other words, this study explores if the Internet plays a positive role in bilateral trade in sectors that are more institutionally intensive as opposed to sectors that are less institutionally intensive. As described earlier, institutions can be described as a set of rules or explicit arrangements that authorizes or prescribes certain business codes of conduct. Some industries have historically required the presence of institutions for trade, where as some other industries have a smaller need for institutional arrangements. As discussed earlier, there are various factors like relationship specificity and other transaction costs that impact the need for institutions. In order to study the effect of technology on bilateral trade, the gravity equation is employed. The gravity equation has been used for such studies by numerous scholars like Freund and Weinhold (2000, 2002, 2004, 2008), Deardorff (1995), McCallum (1995), Frankel, Stein and Wei (1995), Helliwell (1996), and Wei (1996). Anderson (1979) used the Cobb Douglas expenditure system to develop the gravity equation. This equation was originally designed to describe bilateral trade patterns based on the distances between countries as well as their relative economic condition. The standard equation was as follows; Gdpi Gdpj (1)  Tradei,j =  α Distance   ij The basis of the gravity model is that the volume trade between two countries is directly proportional to the size of the economy of each country and is inversely proportional to all the factors that contribute to the cost of trade. The gravity model of trade was used in several 48     empirical studies with considerable success, but there were several scholars that questioned the theoretical justification of the model. The gravity equation is theoretically derived from the Cobb Douglas expenditure system Anderson (1979), and the model has been successful at explaining variation in bilateral trade under both constant returns to scale and increasing returns to scale. Several trade theories like the Ricardian, Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O), and increasing returns to scale (IRS) models (Helpman and Krugman 1985, Deardoff 1998 and Helpman 1998) can be used to derive the gravity equation. However, the biggest criticism of the gravity equation is that it assumes perfect specialization. In response to this critique, several scholars including Evenett and Keller (2001), evaluate the gravity equation with imperfect specialization, and find that when the model is based on increasing returns to scale, the gravity equation is successful in accounting for trade variations across country pairs even when there is no difference in factor proportions (large differences in factor proportions led to perfect specialization in constant returns to scale world). Further, Hummels and Levinshon (1995) and Helpman (1987) in separate studies find that the gravity prediction is an empirical success for developed countries if the model is based on an increasing returns scale. Moreover the gravity equation works for developing countries too because specialization in these countries is driven by factor proportion differences. For the purpose of this dissertation, the gravity equation will be modified to evaluate the effect of various other variables, which are originally unaccounted for in the basic gravity equation. This can be simply done by using a first order log-linearization of equation (1) and is a common practice in studies using the gravity equation. Using this log transformation, the results are interpreted as percent changes. In other words, the coefficients allow to assess the percent effect of a one percent change in the independent variable on the dependent variable. In this case, 49     trade is imports from country i to j in the time period t. Now if we represent trade by total bilateral trade exports between the two countries i,j as importsij and then taking log on both sides of the gravity equation we get the following; (2)  logimportsijt= β1 +  β2   loggdpit  +β3   loggdpjt  +β4   logdistij+  εijt   As commonly done in literature, we add cross-country specific effects. Since we are also interested in the effect of ICT we add the variable “hosts” which captures the number of secure servers in the respective countries. Internet hosts of both countries give us a measure of the extent businesses in the two countries use the Internet. The country effects are captured in the variables β2 to β9. This is represented in equation (3). (3)   logimportsijt= β1   +  β2   loggdpit  +β3   loggdpjt+β4   logpopit+β5   logpopjt+β6   logexrateijt+β7   logdistij +β8   loghostsit+β9   loghostsjt+  εijt   In the above equation, the economic sizes of the two trading countries are accounted along with the distance between the two countries. The income of the exporting country gdpi and the population popi are included to account for supply (larger economies are usually capable of producing more). The income of the importing country gdpj and the population popj are included to account for demand. Both income and population data is collected from the World Bank’s ‘world development indicators’ (WDI) database. Exchange rate data is also collected from the world developmental indicators database as it affects both supply and demand between the two 50     countries. The other gravity equation variable disti,j is the average trading distance between the two trading countries and this is defined as the distance in kilometers between capital cities. This data is standard in the trade literature and is obtained from the IMF Direction of Trade Statistics. Finally data on the Internet availability is collected from the World Development Indicators database. Two variables fixed broadband subscribers and number of secure servers (hosts) are two possible choices for studying the effect of Internet on trade. The use of secure hosts has some limitations (organization of the ISP and hosting market has an influence on the number of secure servers in a county) secure servers (hosts) still capture the use of Internet in businesses better that individual fixed broadband subscriber. The use of encryption technology in Internet transactions is a good indicator of whether the technology is actually used for business purposes or not. Several other studies have used number of Internet users per capita of a country’s population for analysis. This data is based on the number of individual homes that have direct access to Internet and the average size of a family in the corresponding country. While this is a good reflection of the penetration of the Internet in developed countries, it may not be an efficient indicator of penetration in developing countries where Internet resources are heavily shared between multiple users. Internet hosts on the other hand refers to a machine or an application that is connected to the Internet and that has an Internet protocol address assigned to it. Hence, hosts stand to reflect more closely the penetration of Internet in a country. The number of Internet secure servers per capita of population of a country in particular reflects how embedded the Internet is in the commercial activities of a country. 51     Table 2: Data Sources Variable Source Imports by country US Trade Online to the US https://usatrade.census.gov/ Accessed through MSU main library Population World Development Indicators http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators GDP World Development Indicators http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators Exchange Rate World Development Indicators http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators Distance IMF Direction of Trade Statistics http://www.imf.org/external/data.htm Internet Hosts World Development Indicators http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators Data on the dependent variable imports of country i to country j from 2002 onwards was collected from US Trade online that has monthly and annual data on U.S. imports and exports by country and U.S. customs port area with up to 10-digit Harmonized System classification detail. In their study of determinants of bilateral trade flows, Egger (2000) and Matyas (1997) propose the general gravity model which includes time and exporter and importer effects. In this study, a three-way gravity model capturing time and exporter and importer effects is used. The two-way model is a more generalized representation of a three-way model that only includes time invariant main effects. The two-way model includes all time invariant effects (time-invariant main effects and time invariant exporter and importer effects), whereas the three way model only includes the main effect. In addition to time invariant main effects, the two-way model also includes time-invariant bilateral effects, which the three-way model does not include. In this dissertation, the three-way model is adequate for purposes of our analysis because the only time invariant effect of interest is the main effect of ‘distance’ between the two countries. This is 52     because the impact of ‘Internet’ on ‘distance’ and therefore transportation costs may have a crucial role to play in determining trade patterns between countries in certain industries. The statistical software package used to perform the empirical analysis is Stata 11. In this dissertation, both cross sectional pooled regressions using OLS as well as panel data regression is used to estimate the above gravity equation. This approach examines the impact of Internet use on trade assuming that time is constant. The use of two different methods of estimation not only provides a robustness check on the results, but because the two methods have different pros and cons they help capture different aspects of the underlying process. While the OLS estimation is more likely to have better goodness of fit because we are analyzing a larger amount of data, it also helps us eliminate co-trending variables over time (Freund and Weinhold 2004). The assumption the time is constant eliminates the bias that could arise out of two variables having a linear relationship in their trends. Our second method of estimation uses panel data and will help us avoid any omitted variable bias. The two most common ways of panel data estimation is a fixed effects model and a random effects model. According to scholars like Eggar (2002), the model selection depends not only on data properties, but also depends on the interest of the analysis. In general it is assumed that the fixed effects model provides more robust results. However, one major restriction with the fixed effect model is that variables that are collinear with the fixed effects need to be dropped from the model. In our case, data that varies by exporter but is constant for the importer cannot be included in the model. Since the US is our primary importer in our study, using a model with this restriction on variables that are collinear with fixed effects will not work. Hence, the most obvious panel estimation choice here was the random effects model. Further, when we tested the three-way model for each set of regressions, 53     the random effect model was determined to be more appropriate than the fixed effects model after conducting the Hausman test (Wooldridge 2001), that indicates that both the fixed effects and random effects model are consistent, but the random effects model is more efficient. The general rule of thumb as suggested by Judge et al. (1998) was also applied where he states that if the cross sectional units are regarded as random drawings, the number of cross-sectional units N is large (72 in our case) and T is small (9 in our case), the random effects model is more efficient than the fixed effects model. Taylor (1980) also has shown that for T greater than or equal to 3 and N-K greater than or equal to 9, where K is the number of regressors, the random effects model is more efficient. Hence after weighing both theoretical considerations and testing the data, the random effects model seemed more appropriate for this study. Additionally, in this study, regressions where carried out separately for different industries categorized by their institutional intensities. It would be possible to analyze the interactive effect of institutional intensity and Internet by introducing Institutional Intensity as a variable in the gravity equation. This approach was explored but ultimately not chosen because of empirical challenges of using a time invariant variable interacting with ‘Internet Hosts’ in a panel data estimation. 54     5. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Data from the years 2002 to 2010 was used for this study based on data availability. After attempting to ensure that adequate data was available for the main variables in the gravity equation, as well as for the specific industries considered in this study the resulting sample size finally used in the analysis were 72 countries. After cleaning up the data for missing values we end up with a relatively large sample size of 72 countries. Even though data availability was a factor in selection of the sample, the sample does not only contain countries from developed or OECD nations. The sample includes a large number of medium and low income countries with different country characteristics. They also include countries from the American, African, Asian, Australian and European continents. This was critical since distance is an important determinant of trade patterns. Descriptive summary statistics of the variables are available in the appendix by each of the 25 industries. Table 3: List of countries Albania Algeria Australia Azerbaijan Bahamas,  The Bangladesh Belarus Belize Bolivia Bosnia  and  Herzegovina Brazil Bulgaria Burkina  Faso Cambodia Cameroon Canada Chad China Colombia Cote  d'Ivoire Croatia Cyprus Czech  Republic Denmark Dominica Dominican  Republic El  Salvador Estonia Ethiopia Gabon Israel Japan Jordan Kenya Korea,  Rep. Lao  PDR Lebanon Macedonia,  FYR Madagascar Malaysia Maldives Mali Moldova Morocco Mozambique Namibia New  Zealand Nicaragua Oman Panama Papua  New  Guinea Paraguay Peru Philippines 55     Romania Russian  Federation Saudi  Arabia Senegal Slovak  Republic Sri  Lanka Sweden Switzerland Syrian  Arab  Republic Tanzania Thailand Togo Trinidad  and  Tobago Ukraine Uruguay Yemen,  Rep. Zambia Zimbabwe The 25 industries selected are listed below in Table 4, along with their institutional intensities. The trade code used to categorize these industries is their three-digit ISIC (International Standard Industrial Classification) Codes. The institutional intensities used in this study to categorize the industries into low, medium and high institutional intensity sectors are taken from a study conducted by Nunn (2007). Institutional intensity as defined by Nunn (2007) as the share of intermediate inputs that cannot be bought on organized exchanges and is not reference priced. In his study Nathan used the ISIC codes and classified them into the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) 1997 codes in order to calculate the institutional intensities. The data used for human capital and physical capital came from Antweiler and Trefler (2002), while the data for skill and capital intensities came from Bartelsman and Grey (1996). Data about relationship specific investments comes from the 1997 input-output table and data about input’s that are relationship specific came from Rauch (1999). Since the data used to calculate institutional intensities come from specific sources and the calculation of these individual inputs for different time periods are rather time-consuming and beyond the scope of this dissertation, we will assume that the institutional intensities of these different industries have remained fairly constant over the time period of interest in this study. It is possible that some inputs have changed over time and the institutional intensities may have altered, but for the purpose of this study we will assume that for the 25 industries included in the study, the nature of relationship specific investments has not changed drastically over a decade. Since the data used in this study spans from 2002 to 2010, it is reasonable to assume that institutional intensities calculated by Nathan Nunn in 2007 are relatively time appropriate to be used by this study to classify industries. In the 25 industries used for this study we observe that oil and gas is the least institutionally intensive and transportation equipment is 56     the most. As suggested in Nathan Nunn’s paper these numbers make sense for the time period of our study. Petroleum and Coal, and Oil and gas have the least relationship specific investments and that has not changed between 2002 and 2010, while transportation equipment require higher amounts of relationship specific investments as the country specific/location specific factors play a crucial role. It seems that the basic nature of these industries have not changed significantly even if there are some changes in costs or processes. Table 4: Industries and their institutional intensities Industry 324 Petroleum and Coal Products 211 Oil & Gas 325 Chemicals 112 Livestock & Livestock Products 311 Food & Kindred Products 313 Textiles & Fabrics 322 Paper 111 Agricultural Products 327 Nonmetallic Mineral Products 212 Minerals and Ore 326 Plastics & Rubber Products 332 Fabricated Metal Products 113 Forestry Products 312 Beverages & Tobacco Products 321 Wood Products 114 Fish, Fresh/chilled/frozen & Other Marine Products 337 Furniture & Fixtures 316 Leather & Allied Products 323 Printed Matter And Related Products 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components 315 Apparel & Accessories 333 Machinery, Except Electrical 334 Computer & Electronic Products 511 Newspapers, Books & Other Published Matter 336 Transportation Equipment 57     Institutional intensity 0.057654288 0.171116009 0.240283594 0.271475737 0.330635756 0.339565582 0.348113626 0.373506114 0.376581877 0.395959088 0.407733738 0.434656501 0.482169494 0.509090653 0.516188145 0.521434605 0.567659855 0.570608377 0.71282208 0.740018547 0.745411098 0.763578296 0.809803036 0.830137992 0.858740389 Other data used in the modified gravity model comes from several sources and data sources are referenced in table 2. In this study, the dependent variable is US imports and we are interested in understanding the impact of the number of Internet hosts in trading partner nations on US imports in these 25 industries that have varying levels of institutional intensities. An OLS pooled regression model and a modified gravity equation using a random effects model were selected for this study. The OLS pooled regression was used to eliminate the effect of cotrending variables as well as to distinctly capture the effect of distance on trading patterns. In the panel regression, a generalized least squares estimator was used to account for the correlation structure involved in panel data of this nature. The data is analyzed for 72 countries between 2002 and 2010. Each industry was studied separately and then the standardized beta coefficients were compared. Table 5 provides summary statistics of the number of Internet hosts. It can be observed that the mean number of Internet hosts has increased by over ten times. The standard deviation over time seems to decline at first and then exponentially increase. As with most technologies, some early adopters first adopt the technology and this leads to the discovery glitches and issues with the technology. After things have been rectified and improved to make adoption easier, the rest of the population adopts the technology. At this stage, it is possible that different countries follow different trends in adopting the technology depending on their demographic and socio-economic factors. Urban populations are more likely to have access to the technology first, and the time it takes for the rural and less urban area to adopt and get access to the technology might vary depending on several factors. In this study, we proceed to analyze if this difference in access to the information and communication technologies affect trade in different industries differently. 58     Table 5: Summary Statistics of Internet Hosts by Countries in this Study Year 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Mean 641.8361 1784.209 2350.957 2826.333 4214.139 5191.278 6163.324 8199.278 Standard Deviation 4.242641 3.535534 1.414214 1.414214 2.828427 5.656854 9.899495 9.899495 The empirical findings of the OLS estimation are listed below in Table 6. The table depicts only the results of the internet host variable on imports. For results of other variables please refer to the appendix. The focus of this section is the use of Internet (secure hosts) by the exporting country as several studies in the past (Freund and Weinhold 2004) have indicated that it is technology use by the exporting country that impacts trade patterns. Additionally, since we are dealing with the same importing country (US), and the exporting country is the one that benefits by the decreasing production and transaction costs, we will focus on the impact of broadband use by the exporting country on bilateral trade. In order to test for the assumption of normality, we checked the standardized normal probability plot (p-p) and found that the error distributions were not tailed. As discussed above, we tested for the absence of specification errors due to presence of endogenous variables in the model by running Hausman’s endogeneity test for all the independent variables. The chi-squared values for the Hausman tests of all variables indicated that the differences in coefficients are not systematic, thereby ruling out endogeneity captured in an omitted variable bias or because of measurement error. Finally, since multi-collinearity may inflate standard errors, the significance of all the independent variables in our analysis indicates that collinearity between variables is not 59     a significant threat to our results even if present. The large number of observations, high sample variance of explanatory variables and low residual variance makes multi-collinearity less of threat in this analysis. We also checked for heteroscedasticity between variables in the direct impact model and the Breusch-Pagan / Cook-Weisberg (Heij and Boer 2004 and Wooldridge 2001) test for heteroscedasticity ruled out any concerns of deviation from constant variance. A first key finding is that hypothesis 1 is supported in most of the highly institutionally intensive sectors. The hypothesis states that industries that require more intensive institutional arrangements are likely to be positively impacted by the use of broadband technology. In general, industries with institutional intensities smaller than 0.4 are considered low, and ones higher than 0.6 are considered high. However, industries between 0.4 and 0.6 are more ambiguous and can fall into either categories depending on industry sub-classification. If industries with an institutional intensity of above 0.5 are considered, we find that with the exception of the newspaper industry all the industries have a positive standardized beta coefficient that is significant. The newspaper industry could be an exception because of the changing nature of the industry especially a migration towards online news sources. However, the result of the regression in this industry is not statistically significant. Hypothesis 2 is also supported in most industries with a lower institutional intensity, but as discussed in the conceptual framework we find that there a few different factors that may influence the slightly more diverse results. Some of the low institutionally intensive sectors have a significant negative beta coefficient. This indicates that in these sectors, the exporting country may benefit from the use of broadband technology when products are not very relationship specific, because they can export their products to markets that are more favorable with a lot more ease. Another explanation for these negative values is that Oil and Gas, Petroleum, Coal 60     and Agricultural products have low institutional intensity but also have very high demand. They are significantly impacted by trading arrangements/pacts between countries and Internet may have a small role to play. There is also a high transportation cost involved these industries and the affordances that Internet technology provides may not do much to lower these costs. These products are also observed to be ones that are traded in the commodity markets. Commodity markets are characterized by the use of instruments like futures contracts and other derivatives that have been used for decades. This existence of several instruments that already mitigate transaction costs have an impact on how much internet technology can impact these industries in general. Further, the importing country (US) may have also increased domestic production in these industries, and this could be a third explanation for these negative values. We also find that when institutional intensity is closer to 0.5, those industries generally tend to largely benefit from the use of broadband technology. In other words, even when the institutional intensity is low, some of these industrial sectors still do have some transaction costs that cause broadband technology to be of more utility in these sectors. They may also need to use digital processes if their business partners in the importing country use the technology. Some benefit more than others because broadband technology not only improves productivity in these sectors, but these sectors could also benefit from merging tastes and preferences as a result of the technology making the world a more global place. An example of an industry that benefits from this kind of globalization is the food and kindred products industry because knowledge of global foods is increasing demand for specialized food products from certain countries. 61     Table 6: Results of OLS Estimation: Impact of Internet Hosts of Importing Country on Imports Industry Industries with low institutional intensity 324 Petroleum and Coal Products 211 Oil & Gas 325 Chemicals 112 Livestock & Livestock Products 311 Food & Kindred Products 313 Textiles & Fabrics 322 Paper 111 Agricultural Products 327 Nonmetallic Mineral Products 212 Minerals and Ore Industries with high institutional intensity 326 Plastics & Rubber Products 332 Fabricated Metal Products 113 Forestry Product 312 Beverages & Tobacco Products 321 Wood Products 114 Fish, Fresh/chilled/frozen & Other Marine Products 337 Furniture & Fixtures 316 Leather & Allied Products 323 Printed Matter And Related Products 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components 315 Apparel & Accessories 333 Machinery, Except Electrical 334 Computer & Electronic Products 511 Newspapers, Books & Other Published Matter 336 Transportation Equipment Inst. Intensity SE Pvalues Rsquare 0.057654 0.171116 0.240284 0.271476 0.330636 0.339566 0.348114 0.373506 0.376582 0.395959 -0.1921 -0.30136 0.292402 0.717319 0.711624 0.365804 0.430032 -0.18928 0.47875 0.089691 0.099145 0.139822 0.05501 0.116188 0.072082 0.099331 0.097421 0.097067 0.066452 0.161863 0.053 0.032 0 0 0 0 0 0.052 0 0.58 0.2873 0.1623 0.7835 0.1442 0.5784 0.0864 0.2248 0.0464 0.7226 0.004 0.407734 0.434657 0.482169 0.509091 0.516188 0.521435 0.56766 0.570608 0.712822 0.740019 0.745411 0.763578 0.809803 0.830138 0.85874 62     Beta Host 0.202094 0.598627 0.294794 0.826213 0.526411 0.401206 0.538908 0.498816 0.500388 0.264616 0.267445 0.676744 0.638674 -0.22565 0.18737 0.095358 0.05346 0.143966 0.076872 0.094334 0.130518 0.076039 0.105447 0.057191 0.093287 0.104976 0.047444 0.057663 0.19825 0.095041 0.035 0 0.041 0 0 0.002 0 0 0 0.005 0.011 0 0 0.257 0.049 0.0722 0.8157 0.2631 0.6579 0.065 0.3796 0.6623 0.0507 0.798 0.1511 0.0061 0.8455 0.764 0.5575 0.1252 In order to ensure that our results are robust and any omitted variable bias is captured a random effects panel model is also applied. The main empirical findings of the panel data regression study are listed in Table 7. Using the gravity equation, the main control variables used in this study are the GDPs of the importing and exporting country, the population of the two countries, the exchange rate between the two countries and the distance between the two trading countries. As discussed earlier, the two most common ways of panel data estimation is a fixed effects model and a random effect model. Even though most studies involving panel data use the fixed effects model because it provides robust results, we have discussed in the methodology section our reason for using the random effects model. It is often the case that in applied policy studies with specific subjects of interest the random effects model is a better. The impact of Internet hosts (secure servers) on bilateral trade (imports to the US) in 25 different industries is 2 displayed below. The standard beta coefficients, standard errors, the goodness of fit R and the p-values are reported below. The R square value varies between regressions conducted between the different industries. The gravity model used for this study has been kept as generic as possible to include several industries, but this means that there is a possibility of some omitted variable bias or the existence of other endogeneity issues that result in different goodness of fit for these different industries. If one observes the results tables, a lot of industries that exchange goods in the commodity markets have a poorer goodness of fit indicating the possible existence of an omitted variable. Examples of such industries are Minerals and Ore, Wood Products, Plastic and Rubber Products and Petroleum and Gas. These industries have lower goodness of fit in both OLS and panel data estimation. However, for comparison sake the equations for all 25 industries are kept generic and industry specific variables have not been accounted for. Some of 63     these variables have been discussed in the interpretation of the results as it is important to account for these while analyzing the results of the OLS and panel data estimation. 64     Table 7: Results of Panel Data Estimation: Impact of Internet Hosts of Importing Country on Imports Industry Industries with low institutional intensity 324 Petroleum and Coal Products 211 Oil & Gas 325 Chemicals 112 Livestock & Livestock Products 311 Food & Kindred Products 313 Textiles & Fabrics 322 Paper 111 Agricultural Products 327 Nonmetallic Mineral Products 212 Minerals and Ore Industries with high institutional intensity 326 Plastics & Rubber Products 332 Fabricated Metal Products 113 Forestry Products 312 Beverages & Tobacco Products 321 Wood Products 114 Fish, Fresh/chilled/frozen & Other Marine Products 337 Furniture & Fixtures 316 Leather & Allied Products 323 Printed Matter And Related Products 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components 315 Apparel & Accessories 333 Machinery, Except Electrical 334 Computer & Electronic Products 511 Newspapers, Books & Other Published Matter 336 Transportation Equipment Inst. intensity Beta Host Pvalues Rsquare 0.057654288 0.171116009 0.240283594 0.271475737 0.330635756 0.339565582 0.348113626 0.373506114 0.376581877 0.395959087 -0.08605 -0.3514197 0.1035312 0.495167 0.1566343 -0.0028095 0.3122754 -0.1962806 0.2631353 0.0196294 0.145163 0.197219 0.075238 0.157935 0.066187 0.145014 0.140285 0.122963 0.074559 0.411688 0.553 0.075 0.169 0.369 0.018 0.985 0.026 0.11 0 0.0962 0.01 0.125 0.7761 0.1375 0.5318 0.04 0.233 0.0616 0.7199 0.03 0.407733738 0.434656501 0.482169494 0.509090653 0.516188145 0.521434605 0.567659855 0.570608377 0.71282208 0.740018547 0.745411098 0.763578296 0.809803036 0.830137992 0.858740389 0.0049828 0.2472891 -0.0487679 0.1047977 0.4086147 0.1513534 0.3694672 0.0734178 0.2699192 0.346459 0.3351666 0.2852997 0.1079856 -0.1687481 0.176982 0.141387 0.06003 0.112997 0.07147 0.140056 0.105199 0.067559 0.15543 0.074428 0.138668 0.143298 0.060583 0.051087 0.218771 0.118381 0.972 0 0.666 0.143 0.004 0.15 0 0.637 0 0.012 0.019 0 0.035 0.441 0.135 0.0726 0.7967 0.2563 0.5869 0.075 0.3777 0.6568 0.028 0.794 0.1639 0.0215 0.8188 0.723 0.5744 0.1385 65     SE Hypothesis 1 is supported in this study, because we see that Internet use has a positive impact on sectors that have high institutional intensity. Some sectors that have high institutional intensity and have significant results are 333 Machinery, 334 Computer &Electronic Products, 335 Electrical Equipment, 337 Furniture and Fixtures and 315 Apparel & Accessories. While the sign of the standardized beta coefficient is positive in all high institutional industries, a few industries have results that are not statistically significant. This could be because of co-trending variables or because of the smaller number of data points available for analysis using the panel regression method. However, the overall positive sign implies that the use of Internet does benefit industries that have high institutional intensities by reducing transaction costs (both coordination and information costs) and production costs. These industries often need high institutional arrangements to secure themselves against the well-known hold up problem that exist in industries with relationship specific investments. Similar to the OLS results, the newspaper industry is the only industry that is an exception and this is potentially because of the changing nature of the newspaper industry. The panel data results of low institutionally intensive sectors support hypothesis 2, but are slightly different from the OLS estimates. Figure 2 and 3 demonstrates how industries with different institutional intensities are impacted by the use of Internet. These charts depict industries institutional intensities against the estimated parameters for both OLS and panel data estimation. The trend lines on both charts depict an upward trend indicating that Internet has a bigger impact on industries with high institutional intensities. It is interesting that the panel estimation have results that indicated that exporting countries in some low institutionally intensive sector are likely to find other more favorable export markets besides our primary importer US. This is because the use of Internet technology has affordances to provide higher 66     amounts of information and better trade coordination. In this case, we also find that even though the signs of the coefficients support hypothesis 2 they are not statistically significant. Some low institutionally intensive exporting sectors also benefit from the use of the technology as discussed in the conceptual framework earlier. Irrespective of the institutional intensity of a sector, trade takes place when factor proportions are different or there is some specialization. These sectors do have productivity benefits of using broadband technology. The 311 Food and Kindred products, 112 Livestock and Livestock Products, 325 Chemicals, 326 Plastics and Rubber Products, 327 Nonmetallic Mineral Products and 322 Paper are found to be positively impacted by the use of Internet in the exporting country. Most of the estimates were statistically significant indicating that the use of Internet benefits overall productivity whether they are institutionally intensive or not. This indicates that the use of Internet reduces production costs in sectors that naturally have differences in factor proportions that benefit trade. This could indicate that co-ordination costs are reduced or search costs are reduced, and exporting countries are better able to put out information about their products because of the Internet. It could also indicate that with more countries using the Internet, the use of the technology becomes essential for any country that was to do business with other countries in this global world. Earlier, these kind of trading relationships were dictated either by trade agreements or traditional alliances. Now the presence of Internet in exporting firms around the world gives exporters a chance to display information about their products and prices very conveniently. This not only reduces search costs but improves the overall logistics involved in the trading process. 67     Figure 2: OLS Estimate vs. Industry Institutional Intensities 1   Es#mated  Beta   0.8   0.6   0.4   0.2   0   -­‐0.2   -­‐0.4   0   0.3   0.6   Industry  II   0.9   1.2   Figure 3: Panel Estimate vs. Industry Institutional Intensities 0.6   0.5   Es#mated  Beta   0.4   0.3   0.2   0.1   0   -­‐0.1   -­‐0.2   -­‐0.3   -­‐0.4   0   0.3   0.6   Industry  II   68     0.9   There are certain industries that do not fit the general pattern in the results using both estimation techniques. In sector 511 Newspaper, Books and Published Matter, we find that the use of Internet technology over time has a negative impact on trade. This can be explained by understanding the nature of this industry. The Internet has globalized the availability of news and similar published matter. We also find similar results in most industrial sectors using both estimation techniques. The OLS regression has more significant results adding to the robustness of this analysis. The panel data estimation has a larger number of negative beta coefficients in the low institutionally intensive sectors. However, since the results are not significant we cannot state this with statistical certainty. Hypothesis 1 is supported by both estimation techniques, and hypothesis 2 is supported more clearly in the OLS estimation. The panel data regression has more statistically insignificant results and the general goodness of fit is lower. This could be because the number of data points is fewer in the panel data estimation and the methodological assumption driving the pooled approach makes it easier to detect a pattern. The other independent variables and their beta coefficients are also reported industry wise in the appendix of this study. The focus of this study if Internet technology and its effect on bilateral trade with the US and we largely find that the hypothesis H1 and H2 are supported in this study. These results indicate that Internet benefits industries that require high institutional arrangements, but trade between countries is largely benefited from the use of technology irrespective of the institutional intensity. Even in cases where a natural comparative advantage exists, Internet improves the total factor productivity because of its affordances that improve coordination and reduce information costs. The sectors in which Internet is negatively correlated with trade are ones like 324 Petroleum & Coal that have a high demand all around the world and thus traditional ties and alliances still play an important role. These products are not very 69     relationship-specific, and the use of the technology allows the exporting country to export its product on more favorable terms of trade. This changes the patterns of bilateral trade, and gives rise to different groups of winners and losers. One other characteristic of these industries that show negative correlation to trade are the fact that they are products that are sold in commodities markets, and as discussed earlier there are several other instruments used in these market that already mitigate some transaction costs. The use of Internet may not have a significant impact on reducing these costs and may changes the patterns of trade by enabling more countries to enter the market. 70     6. CONCLUSION This study looks at the impact of Internet technology on bilateral trade with the US. The focus is to understand if Internet use impacts industries that require higher institutional arrangements differently from those that do not. The motivation for this comes from studies in the past that have emphasized the importance of institutional arrangements in trade (Levchenko 2008, Kormenos et al. 2001) and from studies that have found that Internet access in a country may have some effect on trade (Freund and Weinhold 2000, 2002, 2004). Internet because of its inherent nature is able provide access to different kinds of information (verbal and visual) almost instantly, and this reduces transaction costs (traditionally managed through the use of institutional arrangements between two countries). However, no study had really attempted to look at the impact of Internet use on trade by categorizing industries based on their institutional intensities. This study is a first attempt to look at how Internet use impacts the importance of traditional institutional arrangements in trade. One must be very careful in interpreting the importance of Internet on trade particularly in highly institutionally intensive sectors because trade is a rather complex phenomenon with various other important variables. This study has tried to control for important variables like the size of the economies, exchange rates and the importance of distance. However, there are certain other variables that might play a role–like cultural factors, languages and similar industry specific variables–that could not be accounted for due to data availability issues. This more parsimonious approach also allowed keeping the basic equation as generic as possible to most industries included. It is very important to acknowledge basic trade theories that state that comparative advantage makes trade possible and differences in factor proportions lead to specialization. This study maintains that differences in factor proportions and increasing returns to scale are the biggest factors leading to trade, and Internet just makes the transaction process 71     easier. In cases where the institutional intensity is high, Internet may have an additional role to play because institutional arrangements themselves become a source of comparative advantage (Levchenko 2008). An OLS and panel data estimation was performed on 25 different industries, and resulted in strong support of hypothesis 1 (with the exception of the newspaper industry), and a weaker support of hypothesis 2 (strongly supported by the OLS estimation, but lack of statistical significance in the panel data estimation). This indicates support for both hypothesis but a weaker one for hypothesis 2. Firstly, increase in use of Internet technology by the exporting country definitely has a positive impact on sectors that require higher institutional arrangements. This indicates that Internet use in businesses (through the use of secure servers and hosts) has the ability to change the way trading alliances are entered into. One often finds that institutional arrangements are of higher quality in more developed nations leading them to be the preferred choice in industries where institutional intensities are high. Internet technology makes it possible for firms in countries with poorer institutional arrangements to enter into trading agreements with firms in the US. The Internet reshapes the importance of institutions because the technology has certain affordances that reduce the need for stronger institutional arrangements. In particular the Internet is able to reduce transaction costs and production costs in these sectors. The second hypothesis that this study tests is that Internet could continue to have positive effect on low institutionally intensive sectors because of productivity effects. However, certain sectors may also see a negative impact on bilateral trade (especially if relationship specificity of investments is very low or negligible) because they now can find other trading partners that perhaps have more favorable terms of trade. There are two processes in play here. If factor differences continue to 72     exist (for example labor being expensive the US will import labor intensive products from countries where labor is cheaper) or a country is highly specialized in a particular industry the US is more likely to import those products from that country. Since there could be a large number of countries with those factor differences, the use of Internet technology could further help reduce production costs and some transaction costs particularly search costs and coordination costs. Countries that specialize in an industrial sector that is competitive therefore also benefit from the use of Internet technology. Internet plays a huge role in reducing production costs giving them an advantage when the market is competitive. However, there is also another factor that plays a role in bilateral trade patterns. If relationship specificity of an industry is low or almost negligible then there is a larger potential for trading goods with another country if for some reason terms of trade with the US is not favorable. This is supported in the OLS estimation and the panel data estimation also shows similar trends but without statistical significance. This study not only emphasizes the importance of Internet in markets that are rather competitive (hypothesis 2), but also suggests that markets that require high institutional arrangements can positively benefit because of unique affordances of Internet technology that result in lower production and transaction costs (hypothesis 1 is strongly supported). There are several ways in which this study can be improved and extended. Firstly, it would be interesting if we could run the same OLS/panel regression on specialized industry sub-groups (based on trade alliances) to confirm the hypothesis. It would also be of interest to obtain a breakdown of costs in every industry to study the impact of broadband of the underlying cost structure of different industries. The above two questions are not dealt with in this study because of data limitations but would certainly be interesting extensions. However, this study is still the first one to look at the impact of Internet on trade by analyzing the how different industries with different 73     institutional intensities are impacted. The results of this study definitely depicts that broadband technology does have an impact on bilateral trade. The nature of this impact is positive in sectors that are very relationship specific, but is more ambiguous in sectors that have low relationship specificity. There are several studies that have attempted to study impact of the Internet on trade, on overall economic productivity. However, this study looks at the impact Internet has on the importance of traditional institutional arrangements during trade. The fact that Internet positively impacts high institutionally intensive sectors does indicate that technological affordances of broadband plays an important role in reducing transaction and production costs in trade. 74     APPENDIX 75     Appendix A: Panel Regression Results Table A.1 321 Wood Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.4945 0.188129 -2.63 0.009 -0.86323 -0.12578 loggdpus 0.214551 0.141992 1.51 0.131 -0.06375 0.49285 logpop 0.337893 0.132072 2.56 0.011 0.079037 0.596749 logpopus -0.18345 -0.60959 0.242694 logexrate 0.009554 0.063326 0.15 0.880 -0.11456 0.133671 logserv 0.408615 0.140056 2.92 0.004 0.13411 0.68312 logservus -0.03687 -0.54369 0.469939 logdist 0.015675 0.07665 0.20 0.838 -0.13456 0.165907 _cons 0.025745 0.093763 0.27 0.784 -0.15803 0.209516 0.217424 -0.84 0.399 0.258583 -0.14 0.887 76     Table A.2 336 Transportation Equipment [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.194526 0.154784 1.26 0.209 -0.10885 0.497896 loggdpus 0.05083 0.149733 0.34 0.734 -0.24264 0.344301 logpop -0.05474 0.103973 -0.53 0.599 -0.25852 0.149045 logpopus -0.10625 0.229324 -0.46 0.643 -0.55572 0.343217 logexrate 0.055489 0.052639 1.05 0.292 -0.04768 0.15866 logserv 0.176982 0.118381 1.50 0.135 -0.05504 0.409004 logservus 0.045679 0.27299 -0.48937 0.58073 logdist -0.13058 _cons 0.148346 0.084547 1.75 0.079 0.17 0.867 0.056815 -2.30 0.022 77     Interval] -0.24194 -0.01923 -0.01736 0.314056 Table A.3 313 Textiles and Fabrics [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.278869 0.199212 1.40 0.162 -0.11158 0.669318 loggdpus 0.039675 0.129757 0.31 0.760 -0.21464 0.293994 logpop -0.02856 0.145004 -0.20 0.844 -0.31276 0.255644 logpopus 0.11211 0.198559 0.56 0.572 -0.27706 0.501279 logexrate 0.079232 0.06533 logserv -0.00281 0.145014 -0.02 0.985 -0.28703 0.281413 logservus -0.11268 0.235658 -0.48 0.633 -0.57456 0.349204 logdist -0.09192 0.087225 -1.05 0.292 -0.26288 0.079039 _cons 0.057293 0.097752 0.59 0.558 1.21 0.225 78     Interval] -0.04881 0.207276 -0.1343 0.248883 Table A.4 323 Printed Matter and Related Products [95% logimports Coef. loggdp Std. Err. z P>z Conf. Interval] 0.626537 0.113618 5.51 0.000 0.40385 0.849224 loggdpus 0.107232 0.054616 1.96 0.050 0.000187 0.214278 logpop -0.01179 0.089256 -0.13 0.895 -0.18673 0.16315 logpopus -0.08231 0.085774 -0.96 0.337 -0.25043 0.085802 logexrate 0.026676 0.033041 0.81 0.419 -0.03808 0.091434 logserv 0.269919 0.074428 3.63 0.000 0.124043 0.415796 logservus -0.09932 0.101073 -0.98 0.326 -0.29742 0.098776 logdist -0.11417 0.054908 -2.08 0.038 -0.22179 -0.00656 _cons -0.12051 0.056613 -2.13 0.033 -0.23147 -0.00955 79     Table A.5 326 Plastics and Rubber Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.249981 0.191642 1.30 0.192 -0.12563 0.625593 loggdpus -0.00207 0.136162 -0.02 0.988 -0.26894 0.264803 logpop -0.08824 0.136566 -0.65 0.518 -0.35591 0.179424 logpopus 0.032521 0.209295 0.16 0.877 -0.37769 0.442732 logexrate -0.17901 -0.30478 -0.05325 logserv 0.004983 0.141387 0.04 0.972 -0.27213 0.282096 logservus -0.00453 0.248307 -0.02 0.985 -0.4912 logdist -0.068 0.080456 -0.85 0.398 -0.22569 0.089692 _cons 0.085373 0.094793 0.90 0.368 0.064168 -2.79 0.005 80     Interval] 0.482147 -0.10042 0.271165 Table A.6 324 Petroleum and Coal Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.642431 0.202706 3.17 0.002 0.245134 1.039729 loggdpus 0.087269 0.125813 0.69 0.488 -0.15932 0.333859 logpop -0.17032 0.148219 -1.15 0.251 -0.46083 0.120182 logpopus -0.0403 0.194548 -0.21 0.836 -0.42161 0.341007 logexrate -0.04353 0.06849 -0.64 0.525 -0.17777 0.090705 logserv -0.08605 0.145163 -0.59 0.553 -0.37056 0.198469 logservus -0.01946 0.230441 -0.08 0.933 -0.47112 0.432196 logdist -0.24316 0.089762 -2.71 0.007 -0.41909 -0.06723 _cons -0.01393 0.099493 -0.14 0.889 -0.20893 0.181077 81     Interval] Table A.7 322 Paper [95% logimports Coef. loggdp Std. Err. z P>z Conf. Interval] 0.245224 0.19068 1.29 0.198 -0.1285 0.61895 loggdpus 0.116775 0.13249 0.88 0.378 -0.1429 0.376451 logpop -0.03383 0.136441 -0.25 0.804 -0.30125 0.233587 logpopus -0.12329 0.202706 -0.61 0.543 -0.52058 0.274007 logexrate 0.112441 0.063357 1.77 0.076 -0.01174 0.236618 logserv 0.312275 0.140285 2.23 0.026 0.037323 0.587228 logservus -0.00723 0.240623 -0.03 0.976 -0.47884 0.464384 logdist -0.02332 0.080601 -0.29 0.772 -0.1813 0.134657 _cons 0.034244 0.093648 0.37 0.715 -0.1493 0.217791 82     Table A.8 211 Oil and Gas [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.755367 0.271322 2.78 0.005 0.223585 1.287149 loggdpus -0.05854 0.169987 -0.34 0.731 -0.39171 0.27463 logpop -0.09677 0.192159 -0.50 0.615 -0.4734 0.279854 logpopus -0.0368 0.257485 -0.14 0.886 -0.54146 0.467865 logexrate 0.051831 0.133466 0.39 0.698 -0.20976 0.313419 logserv -0.35142 -0.73796 0.035123 logservus 0.196439 0.309289 0.64 0.525 -0.40976 0.802635 logdist -0.09959 0.109002 -0.91 0.361 -0.31323 0.114055 _cons -0.2232 0.13524 -0.48826 0.041869 0.197219 -1.78 0.075 -1.65 0.099 83     Interval] Table A.9 511 Newspapers [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 1.272882 0.301984 4.22 0.000 0.681003 1.86476 loggdpus -0.22704 0.143747 -1.58 0.114 -0.50878 0.054697 logpop -0.43077 0.193532 -2.23 0.026 -0.81009 -0.05145 logpopus -0.86906 0.202434 -4.29 0.000 -1.26583 -0.4723 logexrate -0.18289 0.132475 -1.38 0.167 -0.44253 0.07676 logserv -0.16875 0.218771 -0.77 0.441 -0.59753 0.260036 logservus 0.805205 0.240072 3.35 0.001 0.334673 1.275737 logdist -0.01137 0.092567 -0.12 0.902 -0.19279 0.17006 _cons -0.83404 0.157226 -5.30 0.000 -1.14219 -0.52588 84     Interval] Table A.10 327 Nonmetallic Minerals [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.565154 0.118794 4.76 0.000 0.332322 0.797986 loggdpus 0.09295 0.051068 1.82 0.069 -0.00714 0.193041 logpop 0.061412 0.099026 0.62 0.535 -0.13268 0.255499 logpopus -0.1521 0.078241 -1.94 0.052 -0.30545 0.001247 logexrate -0.00021 0.030929 -0.01 0.995 -0.06083 0.060409 logserv 0.263135 0.074559 3.53 0.000 0.117002 0.409268 logservus -0.03305 0.093106 -0.35 0.723 -0.21553 0.149437 logdist -0.11337 0.066453 -1.71 0.088 -0.24362 0.016872 _cons -0.12192 0.065327 -1.87 0.062 -0.24996 0.006116 85     Interval] Table A.11 333 Machinery [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.685443 0.094205 7.28 0.000 0.500806 0.870081 loggdpus 0.07915 0.044157 1.79 0.073 -0.0074 0.165696 logpop -0.0969 0.075726 -1.28 0.201 -0.24532 0.051522 logpopus -0.27857 0.068471 -4.07 0.000 -0.41277 -0.14437 logexrate 0.032502 0.031097 1.05 0.296 -0.02845 0.09345 logserv 0.2853 0.16656 0.404039 logservus 0.114429 0.080673 1.42 0.156 -0.04369 0.272545 logdist -0.07111 -0.16625 0.024037 _cons 0.008652 0.048734 0.18 0.859 -0.08686 0.104168 0.060583 4.71 0.000 0.048545 -1.46 0.143 86     Interval] Table A.12 112 Livestock and Livestock Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.48019 0.210772 -2.28 0.023 -0.89329 -0.06708 loggdpus -0.02325 0.161479 -0.14 0.885 -0.33975 0.293239 logpop 0.482869 0.144847 3.33 0.001 0.198973 0.766765 logpopus -0.47313 -0.96272 0.016466 logexrate 0.080028 0.069884 1.15 0.252 -0.05694 0.216999 logserv 0.495167 0.157935 3.14 0.002 0.18562 0.804715 logservus 0.287928 0.296572 0.97 0.332 -0.29334 0.869199 logdist -0.08523 0.082829 -1.03 0.303 -0.24757 0.07711 _cons 0.01511 0.105239 0.14 0.886 -0.19116 0.221374 0.249798 -1.89 0.058 87     Table A.13 316 Leather & Allied Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.093504 0.220356 0.42 0.671 -0.33839 0.525394 loggdpus 0.117388 0.129962 0.90 0.366 -0.13733 0.372109 logpop -0.112 0.166455 -0.67 0.501 -0.43825 0.214244 logpopus -0.30178 0.200221 -1.51 0.132 -0.69421 0.090643 logexrate -0.0199 0.070865 -0.28 0.779 -0.1588 logserv 0.073418 0.15543 0.47 0.637 -0.23122 0.378056 logservus 0.179958 0.236987 0.76 0.448 -0.28453 0.644443 logdist 0.021453 0.103397 0.21 0.836 -0.1812 _cons 0.061286 0.110074 0.56 0.578 -0.15446 0.277027 88     Interval] 0.11899 0.224106 Table A.14 337 Furniture and Fixtures [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.463165 0.120105 3.86 0.000 0.227763 0.698566 loggdpus 0.076532 0.045257 1.69 0.091 -0.01217 0.165235 logpop 0.063506 0.108419 0.59 0.558 -0.14899 0.276003 logpopus -0.18898 0.070927 -2.66 0.008 -0.32799 -0.04996 logexrate -0.00159 0.028612 -0.06 0.956 -0.05767 0.054487 logserv 0.369467 0.067559 5.47 0.000 0.237054 0.501881 logservus -0.02264 0.083417 -0.27 0.786 -0.18613 0.140853 logdist -0.11852 0.073324 -1.62 0.106 -0.26223 0.025194 _cons -0.11156 0.071105 -1.57 0.117 -0.25092 0.027804 89     Interval] Table A.15 311 Food and Kindred Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. loggdp 0.465457 0.119616 3.89 0.000 0.231014 0.699899 loggdpus -0.03906 -0.127 0.048884 logpop 0.077938 0.111137 0.70 0.483 -0.13989 0.295762 logpopus 0.010817 0.069731 0.16 0.877 -0.12585 0.147487 logexrate -0.07445 -0.13297 -0.01592 logserv 0.156634 0.066187 2.37 0.018 0.02691 0.286359 logservus 0.009429 0.081951 0.12 0.908 -0.15119 0.17005 logdist -0.11488 -0.26847 0.038718 _cons 0.067067 0.074575 0.90 0.368 -0.0791 0.213231 0.04487 z P>z Conf. -0.87 0.384 0.029862 -2.49 0.013 0.078366 -1.47 0.143 90     Interval] Table A.16 114 Fish, Fresh/chilled/Frozen and Other Marine Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.234281 0.203559 1.15 0.250 -0.16469 0.633249 loggdpus 0.032212 0.063586 0.51 0.612 -0.09242 0.156839 logpop 0.316601 0.182843 1.73 0.083 -0.04176 0.674966 logpopus -0.24929 0.097481 -2.56 0.011 -0.44035 -0.05823 logexrate -0.36891 0.128626 -2.87 0.004 -0.62101 -0.1168 logserv 0.151353 0.105199 1.44 0.150 -0.05483 0.35754 logservus 0.158676 0.11443 -0.0656 logdist -0.12666 0.119431 -1.06 0.289 -0.36074 0.107419 _cons -0.27457 0.125176 -2.19 0.028 -0.51991 -0.02923 1.39 0.166 91     Interval] 0.382954 Table A.17 332 Fabricated Metal Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.693771 0.095192 7.29 0.000 0.507198 0.880344 loggdpus 0.041683 0.043525 0.96 0.338 -0.04362 0.12699 logpop -0.05946 0.079316 -0.75 0.453 -0.21491 0.095999 logpopus -0.1548 0.06752 -0.28713 -0.02246 logexrate 0.034692 0.026413 1.31 0.189 -0.01708 0.086461 logserv 0.247289 0.06003 0.129633 0.364945 logservus 0.008725 0.079961 0.11 0.913 -0.148 0.165446 logdist -0.11022 0.053332 -2.07 0.039 -0.21475 -0.00569 _cons -0.06328 0.052586 -1.20 0.229 -0.16635 0.039785 -2.29 0.022 4.12 0.000 92     Interval] Table A.18 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.00324 0.187148 -0.02 0.986 -0.37004 0.363567 loggdpus 0.124741 0.136323 0.92 0.360 -0.14245 0.391928 logpop 0.020105 0.132533 0.15 0.879 -0.23965 0.279865 logpopus -0.0256 0.209477 -0.12 0.903 -0.43616 0.384971 logexrate -0.13305 0.062868 -2.12 0.034 -0.25627 -0.00983 logserv 0.346459 0.138668 2.50 0.012 0.074676 0.618242 logservus -0.11613 0.248598 -0.47 0.640 -0.60337 0.371117 logdist -0.0319 0.077562 -0.41 0.681 -0.18392 0.120115 _cons 0.038735 0.092856 0.42 0.677 -0.14326 0.22073 93     Table A.19 334 Computer and Electronic Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.75498 0.093319 8.09 0.000 loggdpus 0.006996 0.034666 0.20 0.840 -0.06095 0.07494 logpop -0.10255 0.087017 -1.18 0.239 -0.2731 0.068001 logpopus -0.1824 0.053406 -3.42 0.001 -0.28707 -0.07773 logexrate -0.08 0.023048 -3.47 0.001 -0.12517 -0.03482 logserv 0.107986 0.051087 2.11 0.035 0.007857 0.208114 logservus 0.099543 0.062971 1.58 0.114 -0.02388 0.222965 logdist -0.05818 0.061524 -0.95 0.344 -0.17876 0.062405 _cons 0.08208 0.058246 1.41 0.159 -0.03208 0.196241 94     Interval] 0.572078 0.937883 Table A.20 312 Beverages & Tobacco Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. loggdp 0.825902 0.133422 6.19 0.000 0.564399 1.087405 loggdpus 0.030754 0.045396 0.68 0.498 -0.05822 0.119729 logpop -0.26155 -0.49896 -0.02413 logpopus 0.113172 0.07028 -0.02457 0.250918 logexrate -0.0112 -0.17101 0.148606 logserv 0.104798 0.07147 -0.03528 0.244876 logservus -0.13726 0.082644 -1.66 0.097 -0.29923 0.024723 logdist -0.25006 0.082778 -3.02 0.003 -0.4123 -0.08782 _cons -0.29835 0.081187 -3.67 0.000 -0.45748 -0.13923 0.121132 -2.16 0.031 1.61 0.107 0.081537 -0.14 0.891 1.47 0.143 95     Interval] Table A.21 315 Apparel and Accessories [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. z P>z Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.2991 0.190393 -1.57 0.116 -0.67227 0.074061 loggdpus 0.114489 0.154924 0.74 0.460 -0.18916 0.418135 logpop 0.153983 0.131611 1.17 0.242 -0.10397 0.411936 logpopus -0.23219 -0.69816 0.233776 logexrate 0.060178 0.064582 0.93 0.351 -0.0664 0.186757 logserv 0.335167 0.143298 2.34 0.019 0.054307 0.616026 logservus 0.030134 0.2825 -0.52356 0.583825 logdist -8.1E-05 -0.14683 0.146673 _cons 0.051702 0.09686 -0.13814 0.241544 0.237743 -0.98 0.329 0.11 0.915 0.074876 -0.00 0.999 0.53 0.593 96     Table A.22 111 Agricultural Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. loggdp 0.164918 0.161242 1.02 0.306 -0.15111 0.480947 loggdpus 0.195682 0.149698 1.31 0.191 -0.09772 0.489084 logpop 0.051216 0.108904 0.47 0.638 -0.16223 0.264664 logpopus 0.446262 0.230174 1.94 0.053 -0.00487 0.897395 logexrate -0.15676 0.054903 -2.86 0.004 -0.26437 -0.04915 logserv -0.19628 0.122963 -1.60 0.110 -0.43728 0.044723 logservus -0.56125 0.273946 -2.05 0.040 -1.09818 -0.02433 logdist 0.056817 0.060028 0.95 0.344 -0.06084 0.17447 _cons -0.04929 -0.21869 0.120114 0.08643 z P>z Conf. -0.57 0.569 97     Interval] Appendix B: OLS Regression Results Table B.1 324 Petroleum and Coal Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.803892 0.129284 6.22 0 0.549816 1.057968 loggdpus 0.076624 0.169984 0.45 0.652 -0.25744 0.410685 logpop -0.29005 0.001 -0.45338 -0.12673 logpopus 0.000778 0.261638 0 0.998 -0.51341 0.514961 logexrate -0.07745 0.043198 -1.79 0.074 -0.16235 0.007441 logserv -0.1921 0.099145 -1.94 0.053 -0.38695 0.002745 logservus -0.02407 0.311853 -0.08 0.939 -0.63694 0.588803 logdist -0.21434 0.041939 -5.11 0 -0.29676 -0.13192 _cons -0.01145 0.086693 0.13 0.895 -0.18183 0.158919 0.083107 -3.49 98     Table B.2 111 Agriculture Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. In terval] loggdp 0.171429 0.125028 1.37 0.171 -0.07425 0.417113 loggdpus 0.201473 0.166245 1.21 0.226 -0.1252 0.52815 logpop 0.057257 0.080895 0.71 0.479 -0.1017 0.216219 logpopus 0.41747 0.254807 1.64 0.102 -0.08323 0.918173 logexrate -0.13565 0.041769 -3.25 0.001 -0.21773 -0.05357 logserv -0.18928 0.097067 -1.95 0.052 -0.38002 0.001455 logservus -0.54899 0.304112 -1.81 0.072 -1.14658 0.048601 logdist 0.045467 0.041408 1.1 0.273 -0.0359 0.126835 _cons -0.05744 0.494 -0.22238 0.107493 0.083937 0.68 99     Table B.3 315 Apparel and Accessories Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.1979 0.135216 -1.46 0.144 -0.46361 0.067798 loggdpus 0.117198 0.180004 0.65 0.515 -0.23651 0.470907 logpop 0.082451 0.087542 0.94 0.347 -0.08957 0.254471 logpopus -0.17052 0.535 -0.71061 0.369561 logexrate 0.055385 0.045025 1.23 0.219 -0.03309 0.14386 logserv 0.267445 0.104976 2.55 0.011 0.061166 0.473723 logservus 0.001633 0.328113 0 0.996 -0.64311 0.64638 logdist -0.00118 0.044836 -0.03 0.979 -0.08928 0.086928 _cons 0.05265 0.09069 0.562 -0.12555 0.230863 0.27485 t -0.62 0.58 100     Table B.4 312 Beverage and Tobacco Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.05092 0.099197 -0.51 0.608 -0.24593 0.144096 loggdpus 0.076026 0.128792 0.59 0.555 -0.17717 0.329224 logpop 0.164436 0.064039 2.57 0.011 0.038538 0.290334 logpopus 0.047406 0.196893 0.24 0.81 -0.33967 0.434486 logexrate 0.053022 0.035583 1.49 0.137 -0.01693 0.122975 logserv 0.826213 0.076872 10.75 0 0.675086 0.977339 logservus -0.2393 0.235838 -1.01 0.311 -0.70295 0.224342 logdist -0.20314 0.030314 -6.7 0 -0.26274 -0.14355 _cons -0.22808 0.065689 -3.47 0.001 -0.35722 -0.09894 101     Table B.5 325 Chemical Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.679811 0.072038 9.44 0 0.538234 0.821387 loggdpus 0.117185 0.094319 1.24 0.215 -0.06818 0.302551 logpop -0.12226 0.046503 -2.63 0.009 -0.21365 -0.03087 logpopus -0.22451 0.143976 -1.56 0.12 -0.50747 0.058449 logexrate -0.02964 0.023707 -1.25 0.212 -0.07623 0.016954 logdist -0.12953 0.023001 -5.63 0 -0.17473 -0.08432 logserv 0.292402 0.05501 0 0.184291 0.400513 logservus -0.01386 0.171732 -0.08 0.936 -0.35137 0.323645 _cons -0.02716 0.047602 0.57 0.569 -0.12072 0.066386 5.32 102     Table B.6 334 Computer and Electronics Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.234847 0.07415 3.17 0.002 0.089138 0.380555 loggdpus 0.024643 0.097683 0.25 0.801 -0.16731 logpop 0.130957 0.047566 2.75 0.006 0.037487 0.224426 logpopus -0.25461 0.088 -0.54681 0.037594 logexrate 0.022221 0.024469 0.91 0.364 -0.02586 0.070304 logserv 0.638674 0.057663 11.08 0 0.525363 0.751986 logservus 0.045732 0.177697 0.26 0.797 -0.30345 0.394917 logdist -0.01108 0.648 -0.0588 0.036636 _cons 0.110333 0.049108 2.25 0.025 0.013803 0.206803 0.1487 -1.71 0.024283 -0.46 103     0.216597 Table B.7 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances and Components [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. loggdp 0.01989 t P>t Conf. Interval] 0.120161 0.17 0.869 -0.21623 0.256008 loggdpus 0.103966 0.159961 0.65 0.516 -0.21036 0.418292 logpop 0.010075 0.077794 0.13 0.897 -0.14279 0.162942 logpopus 0.082012 0.244247 0.34 0.737 -0.39794 0.561961 logexrate -0.1148 0.004 -0.19342 -0.03617 logserv 0.264616 0.093287 2.84 0.005 0.081306 0.447927 logservus -0.15667 0.29158 -0.54 0.591 -0.72962 0.416293 logdist -0.02665 0.039844 -0.67 0.504 -0.10494 0.051646 _cons 0.066293 0.080592 0.82 0.411 -0.09207 0.224658 0.040012 -2.87 104     Table B.8 332 Fabricated Metal Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.311619 0.070042 4.45 0 0.173955 0.449283 loggdpus 0.045627 0.089891 0.51 0.612 -0.13105 logpop 0.11748 0.044219 2.66 0.008 0.030569 0.204391 logpopus -0.19779 0.138025 -1.43 0.153 -0.46907 0.073494 logexrate 0.003398 0.022577 0.15 0.88 -0.04098 0.047773 logserv 0.598627 0.05346 0 0.493554 0.7037 logservus -0.02521 0.165003 -0.15 0.879 -0.34952 0.299094 logdist -0.06034 0.021805 -2.77 0.006 -0.1032 -0.01748 _cons -0.02449 0.045764 0.54 0.593 -0.11444 0.065457 11.2 105     0.222305 Table B.9 114 Fish and Marine Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.22848 0.162351 -1.41 0.16 -0.5479 0.090936 loggdpus 0.032036 0.188769 0.17 0.865 -0.33936 0.403429 logpop 0.558507 0.098507 5.67 0 0.364699 0.752316 logpopus -0.26866 0.285126 -0.94 0.347 -0.82964 0.292308 logexrate -0.30569 0.056487 -5.41 0 -0.41682 -0.19455 logserv 0.401206 0.130518 3.07 0.002 0.144418 0.657994 logservus 0.116803 0.338734 0.34 0.73 -0.54964 0.783247 logdist -0.11575 0.040033 -2.89 0.004 -0.19452 -0.03699 _cons -0.13306 0.095294 -1.4 0.164 -0.32054 0.054432 106     Table B.10 311 Food and Kindred Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.18462 0.092756 -1.99 0.047 -0.36689 -0.00235 loggdpus 0.004231 0.122696 0.03 0.973 -0.23687 0.245338 logpop 0.398755 0.05991 0 0.281028 0.516481 logpopus 0.043662 0.188519 0.23 0.817 -0.32679 0.414115 logexrate -0.00114 0.971 -0.06176 0.059478 logserv 0.711624 0.072082 9.87 0 0.569978 0.853269 logservus -0.16072 0.224737 -0.72 0.475 -0.60234 0.280904 logdist -0.11454 0.030549 -3.75 0 -0.17457 -0.05451 _cons 0.065883 0.061862 1.07 0.287 -0.05568 0.187446 6.66 0.030848 -0.04 107     Table B.11 113 Forestry Products Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.014146 0.183627 0.08 0.939 -0.34705 0.375345 loggdpus 0.015967 0.200512 0.08 0.937 -0.37845 0.41038 logpop 0.382458 0.108205 3.53 0 0.169617 0.595299 logpopus -0.26591 -0.85 0.393 -0.87779 0.345976 logexrate 0.049501 0.05748 0.86 0.39 -0.06356 0.162566 logserv 0.294794 0.143966 2.05 0.041 0.011608 0.57798 logservus 0.17207 0.47 0.641 -0.55262 0.896762 logdist 0.029023 0.046061 0.63 0.529 -0.06158 0.119626 _cons -0.08224 0.425 -0.2847 0.120215 0.31107 0.36842 0.102926 0.8 108     Table B.12 337 Furniture and Fixtures [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.188415 0.098457 1.91 0.056 -0.00512 0.38195 loggdpus 0.072763 0.120445 0.6 0.546 -0.16399 0.309521 logpop 0.206944 0.061265 3.38 0.001 0.086518 0.327371 logpopus -0.13779 0.185832 -0.74 0.459 -0.50308 0.227494 logexrate -0.06829 0.030532 -2.24 0.026 -0.1283 -0.00827 logserv 0.538908 0.076039 7.09 0 0.38944 0.688375 logservus -0.07264 0.221804 -0.33 0.743 -0.50864 0.363356 logdist -0.1079 0.029027 -3.72 0 -0.16496 -0.05084 _cons -0.05363 0.0613 0.382 -0.17412 0.066868 0.87 109     Table B.13 316 Leather and Allied Products Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.41388 0.135824 -3.05 0.002 -0.68077 -0.14698 loggdpus 0.145447 0.180812 0.8 0.422 -0.20985 0.500746 logpop 0.127875 0.087935 1.45 0.147 -0.04492 0.300668 logpopus -0.39564 0.153 -0.93815 0.14687 logexrate 0.090315 0.045227 2 0.046 0.001443 0.179188 logserv 0.498816 0.105447 4.73 0 0.291611 0.706021 logservus 0.167301 0.329587 0.51 0.612 -0.48034 0.814945 logdist 0.036487 0.045038 0.81 0.418 -0.05201 0.124987 _cons 0.086993 0.091098 0.95 0.34 -0.09202 0.266001 0.276085 -1.43 110     Table B.14 112 Livestock Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.702 0.148825 -4.72 0 -0.99448 -0.40951 loggdpus 0.006837 0.192769 0.04 0.972 -0.37201 0.385684 logpop 0.573186 0.094736 6.05 0 0.387002 0.759369 logpopus -0.5427 0.068 -1.12595 logexrate 0.102001 0.048579 2.1 0.036 0.006529 0.197472 logserv 0.717319 0.116188 6.17 0 0.488977 0.94566 logservus 0.256452 0.354022 0.72 0.469 -0.4393 0.952205 logdist -0.04243 0.372 -0.13584 0.050981 _cons 0.014706 0.098481 0.15 0.881 -0.17884 0.208249 0.296774 -1.83 0.047531 -0.89 111     0.040542 Table B.15 333 Machinery Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.264997 0.061999 4.27 0 0.143149 0.386844 loggdpus 0.11163 0.081007 1.38 0.169 -0.04757 logpop 0.086333 0.039949 2.16 0.031 0.007821 0.164846 logpopus -0.34035 0.12445 -2.73 0.006 -0.58493 -0.09577 logexrate -0.00326 0.02046 -0.16 0.873 -0.04347 0.036945 logserv 0.676744 0.047444 14.26 0 0.583503 0.769985 logservus 0.06293 0.148325 0.42 0.672 -0.22858 0.354435 logdist -0.00791 0.019765 -0.4 0.689 -0.04676 0.030931 _cons 0.024047 0.040906 0.59 0.557 -0.05635 0.10444 112     0.270833 Table B.16 327 Nonmetallic Mineral Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.312985 0.085075 3.68 0 0.145766 0.480205 loggdpus 0.064109 0.109894 0.58 0.56 -0.15189 logpop 0.213855 0.053771 3.98 0 0.108164 0.319545 logpopus -0.1945 0.249 -0.52591 0.13691 logexrate 0.018904 0.027377 0.69 0.49 -0.03491 0.072716 logserv 0.47875 0.066452 7.2 0 0.348136 0.609365 logservus -0.03587 0.2018 0.859 -0.43252 0.360784 logdist -0.09386 0.026248 -3.58 0 -0.14545 -0.04227 _cons -0.05983 0.056302 -1.06 0.289 -0.17049 0.050836 0.168608 -1.15 -0.18 113     0.280112 Table B.17 511 Newspaper Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 1.426555 0.245628 5.81 0 0.941164 1.911945 loggdpus -0.2968 0.239003 -1.24 0.216 -0.7691 0.175495 logpop -0.53065 0.134136 -3.96 0 -0.79572 -0.26558 logpopus -0.82103 0.337261 -2.43 0.016 -1.4875 -0.15456 logexrate -0.16856 0.068575 -2.46 0.015 -0.30408 -0.03305 logserv -0.22565 0.19825 0.257 -0.61742 0.166113 logservus 0.872561 0.399686 2.18 0.031 0.082732 1.66239 logdist -0.03452 0.042514 -0.81 0.418 -0.11853 0.049493 _cons -0.79145 0.134849 -5.87 0 -1.05792 -0.52497 -1.14 114     Table B.18 211 Oil and Gas Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.642726 0.186227 3.45 0.001 0.276131 1.009321 loggdpus -0.05352 0.242283 -0.22 0.825 -0.53046 0.42342 logpop -0.01686 0.115898 -0.15 0.884 -0.24501 0.211292 logpopus -0.21558 0.367715 -0.59 0.558 -0.93944 0.508278 logexrate 0.051765 0.068659 0.75 0.452 -0.08339 0.186922 logserv -0.30136 0.032 -0.5766 -0.02611 logservus 0.334794 0.441261 0.76 0.449 -0.53384 1.203432 logdist -0.05167 0.049809 -1.04 0.3 -0.14972 0.046383 _cons -0.08746 0.125577 0.7 0.487 -0.33467 0.159738 0.139822 -2.16 115     Table B.19 322 Paper Industry logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t [95 Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.0262451 1.256974 0.21 0.835 -.2207588 0.2732489 loggdpus 0.138371 0.167689 0.83 0.410 -.1911488 0.467892 logpop 0.085947 .0813482 1.06 0.291 -0.739075 0.2458018 logpopus 0.076553 -0.25469 0.764 -.5770381 0.423932 logexrate 0.098299 0.042037 2.34 0.02 0.015694 0.180904 logserv .4300322 .0974211 4.41 .000 .2385931 .6214713 logservus -0.07952 0.30429 0.794 -0.677475 0.518426 logdist -.0250036 .0415246 -.60 0.547 -.1066023 0.0565951 _cons 0.0413514 0.084074 0.49 0.623 -.1238598 0.2065626 -0.3 -0.26 116     Table B.20 326 Plastics Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.000335 0.122828 0 0.998 -0.24102 0.241693 loggdpus 0.031068 0.163512 0.19 0.849 -0.29023 0.35237 logpop 0.030113 0.079521 0.38 0.705 -0.12615 0.186372 logpopus 0.087903 0.249668 0.35 0.725 -0.4027 0.578504 logexrate -0.04344 0.289 -0.12381 0.036931 logserv 0.202094 0.095358 2.12 0.035 0.014715 0.389473 logservus -0.11457 0.298051 -0.38 0.701 -0.70025 0.4711 logdist -0.0648 0.040728 -1.59 0.112 -0.14483 0.015234 _cons 0.101313 0.082381 1.23 0.219 -0.06057 0.263192 0.0409 -1.06 117     Table B.21 323 Printed Matter and Related Products [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp 0.405238 0.075421 5.37 0 0.256984 0.553493 loggdpus 0.107945 0.094684 1.14 0.255 -0.07818 0.294065 logpopus -0.07895 0.147435 -0.54 0.593 -0.36876 0.210861 logpop 0.13 0.048079 2.7 0.007 0.035492 0.224509 logexrate 0.038183 0.024112 1.58 0.114 -0.00921 logserv 0.500388 0.057191 8.75 0 0.387969 0.612808 logservus -0.1588 0.175431 -0.91 0.366 -0.50365 0.186041 logdist -0.08983 0.022948 -3.91 0 -0.13494 -0.04473 _cons -0.1173 0.048968 -2.4 0.017 -0.21356 -0.02104 118     0.08558 Table B.22 313 Textile Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.16621 0.127567 -1.3 0.193 -0.41689 0.084469 loggdpus 0.101689 0.170155 0.6 0.55 -0.23268 0.436056 logpop 0.167939 0.082616 2.03 0.043 0.005592 0.330286 logpopus 0.077162 0.258723 0.3 0.766 -0.43125 logexrate 0.149528 0.042598 3.51 0 0.065821 0.233236 logserv 0.365804 0.099331 3.68 0 0.170611 0.560998 logservus -0.1806 0.309073 -0.58 0.559 -0.78795 0.426752 logdist -0.05075 0.042098 -1.21 0.229 -0.13348 0.031974 _cons 0.077049 0.085507 0.9 0.368 -0.09098 0.245077 119     0.585573 Table B.23 336 Transportation Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] 1.1 0.272 -0.10582 0.375293 loggdp 0.134735 0.12242 loggdpus 0.051924 0.162969 0.32 0.75 -0.26831 0.372161 logpop -0.03108 0.079257 -0.39 0.695 -0.18682 0.124664 logpopus -0.04215 0.24884 0.866 -0.53113 0.446821 logexrate 0.027111 0.040764 0.67 0.506 -0.05299 0.107213 logserv 0.18737 0.095041 1.97 0.049 0.000612 0.374128 logservus -0.00266 0.297063 -0.01 0.993 -0.5864 0.581068 logdist -0.12116 0.040593 -2.98 0.003 -0.20093 -0.04139 _cons 0.157787 0.082108 1.92 0.055 -0.00356 0.31913 -0.17 120     Table B.24 321 Wood Industry [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. t P>t Conf. Interval] loggdp -0.61342 0.121527 -5.05 0 -0.85223 -0.37462 loggdpus 0.230696 0.161481 1.43 0.154 -0.08662 0.548015 logpop 0.36201 0.078445 4.61 0 0.207862 0.516158 logpopus -0.15544 0.246312 -0.63 0.528 -0.63945 0.328579 logexrate 0.059183 0.040342 1.47 0.143 -0.02009 0.138458 logserv 0.526411 0.094334 5.58 0 0.34104 0.711783 logservus -0.08017 0.785 -0.65808 0.497744 logdist 0.039144 0.04004 0.98 0.329 -0.03954 0.117825 _cons 0.052597 0.081096 0.65 0.517 -0.10676 0.211955 0.294093 -0.27 121     Table B.25 212 Minerals and Ore [95% logimports Coef. Std. Err. loggdp -0.12061 loggdpus -0.15167 logpop t P>t Conf. Interval] 0.204529 -0.59 0.556 -0.5232 0.281971 0.260524 -0.58 0.561 -0.66447 0.361131 0.042427 0.131162 0.32 0.747 -0.21575 0.300599 logpopus -0.12651 0.402629 -0.31 0.754 -0.91903 0.666003 logexrate -0.0244 0.070516 -0.35 0.73 -0.1632 0.114395 logserv 0.089691 0.161863 0.55 0.58 -0.22891 0.408295 logservus 0.19615 0.477506 0.41 0.682 -0.74375 1.13605 logdist 0.016198 0.062252 0.26 0.795 -0.10634 0.138733 _cons 0.044138 0.132096 0.33 0.739 -0.21587 0.30415 122     Appendix C: Summary Statistics Table C.1 111 Agriculture Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 645 5.026783 1.670139 0 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 123     6.39693 13.0103 Table C.2 111 Agriculture Correlation and Covariances Variable logimports loggdp logimports 1 loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 0.0964 1 -0.0627 0.0827 1 0.1532 0.6845 0.0759 1 logpopus -0.0626 0.1016 0.9009 0.093 1 logexrate -0.1032 -0.1851 0.0401 0.0716 0.0307 1 logserv -0.0134 0.7915 0.2268 0.2353 0.2628 -0.3482 1 logservus -0.0747 0.0932 0.9469 0.0865 0.9813 0.0358 0.2538 0.084 0.04 0.0277 0.3101 0.0293 0.2313 -0.1726 loggdpus logpop logdist 124     Table C.3 112 Livestock & Livestock Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 594 4.43017 2.077538 0 6.216606 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 125     13.0103 Table C.4 112 Livestock & Livestock Products Correlations and Covariance Variable logimports loggdp logimports 1 loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 0.2205 1 -0.0326 0.0778 1 0.2221 0.6868 0.0738 1 -0.0495 0.0963 0.8999 0.0948 1 logexrate 0.0045 -0.1573 0.0345 0.0883 0.0339 1 logserv 0.2214 0.7947 0.2202 0.2381 0.2528 -0.3287 1 logservus -0.0397 0.0897 0.9466 0.0873 0.9814 0.0341 0.2466 logdist -0.0057 0.0657 0.0326 0.3302 0.0353 0.2211 -0.1578 loggdpus logpop logpopus 126     Table C.5 114 Fish, Fresh/Chilled/Frozen and Other Marine Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std. Min Max logimports 425 15.65378 3.117196 7.696213 21.41443 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 127     13.0103 Table C.6 114 Fish, Fresh/Chilled/Frozen and Other Marine Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports loggdp logimports loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.5049 1 loggdpus 0.0652 0.0954 1 logpop 0.4111 0.6962 0.0951 1 logpopus 0.0676 0.1215 0.9036 0.124 1 -0.3126 -0.1113 -0.0024 0.1828 -0.0033 1 logexrate logserv 0.4396 0.7912 0.2659 0.2249 0.2985 -0.3482 1 logservus 0.0676 0.1121 0.949 0.114 0.981 -0.0002 0.2902 -0.0833 0.1017 0.0135 0.3347 0.0164 logdist 128     0.2497 -0.1214 Table C.7 211 Oil and Gas Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 376 2.986719 2.285671 0 5.513429 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 129     13.0103 Table C.8 211 Oil and Gas Correlations and Covariance Variable logimports loggdp logimports loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.3875 1 loggdpus 0.0562 0.0365 1 logpop 0.3579 0.7424 0.0641 1 logpopus 0.0523 0.0444 0.8994 0.089 1 logexrate 0.0533 -0.0974 -0.0718 0.0571 -0.0569 1 logserv 0.226 0.804 0.2113 0.3409 0.2267 -0.2874 1 logservus 0.0583 0.041 0.947 0.0798 0.9812 -0.0599 0.2264 logdist 0.0485 0.1501 -0.0025 0.302 0.0166 130     0.1497 -0.0244 Table C.9 311 Food and Kindred Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 629 15.85557 3.360476 7.667158 23.11375 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 131     13.0103 Table C.10 311 Food and Kindred Products Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports loggdp logimports loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.6799 1 loggdpus 0.0687 0.0871 1 0.408 0.6852 0.0834 1 0.0969 0.1043 0.9002 0.0987 1 -0.2326 -0.1764 0.0326 0.0753 0.0254 1 logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 0.7045 0.7921 0.2257 0.2363 0.2618 -0.3437 1 logservus 0.0849 0.0966 0.9464 0.0933 0.9813 0.0299 0.2519 -0.1365 0.0473 0.0276 0.3138 0.0302 0.2211 -0.1666 logdist 132     Table C.11 312 Beverages and Tobacco Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 492 14.47918 3.027795 7.72533 20.63566 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 133     13.0103 Table C.12 312 Beverages and Tobacco Products Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.6517 1 loggdpus 0.0569 0.0806 1 logpop 0.2775 0.7368 0.0863 1 logpopus 0.0778 0.0978 0.9002 0.1071 1 -0.2093 -0.0837 0.0266 0.0975 0.034 1 logexrate logserv 0.7778 0.7775 0.2232 0.2844 0.2588 -0.2923 1 logservus 0.0691 0.0915 0.9467 0.1013 0.9813 0.0354 0.2515 -0.2208 0.1289 0.0427 0.3264 0.0455 logdist 134     0.176 -0.0741 Table C.13 313 Textiles and Fabrics Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 634 4.3212 2.200151 0 6.251904 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 135     13.0103 Table C.14 313 Textiles and Fabrics Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.2359 1 loggdpus 0.0713 0.0883 1 logpop 0.1444 0.6843 0.0795 1 logpopus 0.0745 0.1028 0.902 0.094 1 logexrate 0.0567 -0.1813 0.0345 0.0701 0.0278 1 logserv 0.2586 0.7893 0.236 0.2319 0.2665 -0.3458 1 logservus 0.0713 0.0959 0.9477 0.0883 0.9814 0.031 0.2594 -0.0436 0.0435 0.0278 0.3109 0.0307 logdist 136     0.2245 -0.1687 Table C.15 315 Apparel and Accessories Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 647 5.259247 1.37909 0 6.437752 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 137     13.0103 Table C.16 315 Apparel and Accessories Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.0629 1 loggdpus 0.0168 0.0841 1 0.007 0.6845 0.0762 1 logpopus -0.002 0.1029 0.9013 0.0933 1 logexrate 0.0011 -0.1863 0.0318 0.0703 0.023 1 logserv 0.1108 0.7911 0.2299 0.2353 0.2658 -0.3523 1 logservus 0.0047 0.0946 0.9473 0.0868 0.9813 0.0276 0.2568 -0.0226 0.0402 0.0283 0.3101 0.0299 logpop logdist 138     0.229 -0.1717 Table C.17 316 Leather and Allied Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 647 5.031027 1.669294 0 6.400258 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 139     13.0103 Table C.18 316 Leather and Allied Products Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.0559 1 loggdpus 0.0621 0.0841 1 -0.0314 0.6845 0.0762 1 logpopus 0.0317 0.1029 0.9013 0.0933 1 logexrate 0.0056 -0.1863 0.0318 0.0703 0.023 1 logserv 0.1655 0.7911 0.2299 0.2353 0.2658 -0.3523 1 logservus 0.0461 0.0946 0.9473 0.0868 0.9813 0.0276 0.2568 -0.0112 0.0402 0.0283 0.3101 0.0299 logpop logdist 140     0.229 -0.1717 Table C.19 321 Wood Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 632 4.887999 1.788474 0 6.356108 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 141     13.0103 Table C.20 321 Wood Products Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.0499 1 loggdpus 0.1056 0.0895 1 logpop 0.0853 0.6826 0.0827 1 logpopus 0.0798 0.1087 0.9011 0.0986 1 logexrate 0.0199 -0.1891 0.027 0.0709 0.0197 1 logserv 0.1163 0.7923 0.2287 0.2332 0.2648 -0.3574 1 0.089 0.0998 0.9472 0.0923 0.9812 0.0233 0.255 0.0528 0.0408 0.0301 0.3112 0.0313 0.2303 -0.1711 logservus logdist 142     Table C.21 322 Paper Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 630 3.819961 2.409088 0 6.144186 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 143     13.0103 Table C.22 322 Paper Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.4299 1 loggdpus 0.0971 0.0915 1 logpop 0.2113 0.6888 0.0768 1 logpopus 0.0911 0.1055 0.902 0.0939 1 -0.0568 -0.1698 0.0211 0.0723 0.0201 1 logexrate logserv logservus logdist 0.463 0.7883 0.2418 0.2372 0.2713 -0.3354 1 0.0924 0.0984 0.9477 0.0874 0.9813 0.0225 0.2639 -0.0523 0.0494 0.0227 0.3117 0.028 144     0.2182 -0.1627 Table C.23 323 Printed Matter and Related Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 533 12.94797 3.321482 7.649693 21.55362 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 145     13.0103 Table C.24 323 Printed Matter and Related Products Correlations and Covariances Variables logimports loggdp logimports 1 loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 0.8539 1 0.005 0.0572 1 logpop 0.4814 0.6939 0.0666 1 logpopus 0.0024 0.0646 0.9001 0.0746 1 -0.2142 -0.1703 0.0391 0.0733 0.0363 1 loggdpus logexrate logserv 0.8065 0.7878 0.2049 0.2386 0.2347 -0.3371 1 logservus 0.0024 0.0635 0.9462 0.0722 0.9818 0.0368 0.2311 -0.0859 0.0728 0.0433 0.3072 0.043 logdist 146     0.2118 -0.1232 Table C.25 324 Petroleum and Coal Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 612 3.015609 2.524168 0 5.924256 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 147     13.0103 Table C.26 324 Petroleum and Coal Products Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.4452 1 loggdpus 0.0212 0.0742 1 0.149 0.6955 0.0815 1 0.0132 0.0883 0.901 0.0998 1 -0.1993 -0.1467 0.0353 0.0781 0.0347 1 logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 0.4254 0.7805 0.2249 0.2358 0.2538 -0.3187 1 logservus 0.0147 0.0828 0.9471 0.0929 0.9815 0.0362 0.2488 -0.2413 0.0726 0.0364 0.3197 0.0428 0.2081 -0.1444 logdist 148     Table C.27 326 Plastic & Rubber Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 648 4.620459 2.035555 0 6.329721 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 149     13.0103 Table C.28 326 Plastic & Rubber Products Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.2226 1 loggdpus 0.0394 0.0841 1 logpop 0.0634 0.6845 0.0762 1 logpopus 0.0505 0.1029 0.9013 0.0933 1 -0.1537 -0.1863 0.0318 0.0703 0.023 1 logexrate logserv 0.2804 0.7911 0.2299 0.2353 0.2658 -0.3523 1 logservus 0.0451 0.0946 0.9473 0.0868 0.9813 0.0276 0.2568 -0.1207 0.0402 0.0283 0.3101 0.0299 logdist 150     0.229 -0.1717 Table C.29 327 Non Metallic Mineral Ores Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 546 14.53994 3.601517 5.568345 22.36176 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 151     13.0103 Table C.30 327 Non Metallic Mineral Ores Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.8173 1 loggdpus 0.0051 0.0738 1 logpop 0.4968 0.6905 0.0873 1 logpopus 0.0086 0.0949 0.9002 0.1083 1 -0.2045 -0.1636 0.0298 0.0927 0.023 1 logexrate logserv 0.7505 0.7912 0.2137 0.2389 0.2475 -0.345 1 logservus 0.0074 0.0876 0.9469 0.1009 0.9814 0.0253 0.2423 -0.0796 0.0714 0.0329 0.3155 0.0348 0.2176 -0.1413 logdist 152     Table C.31 332 Fabricated Metal Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 566 14.26057 4.093736 7.613325 23.42445 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 153     13.0103 Table C.32 332 Fabricated Metal Products Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.8443 1 loggdpus 0.0135 0.0675 1 logpop 0.4397 0.6942 0.0751 1 logpopus 0.0248 0.091 0.9003 0.093 1 logexrate -0.2672 -0.171 0.0381 0.0827 0.0303 1 logserv 0.8421 0.7919 0.2119 0.245 0.2511 -0.3458 1 logservus 0.0209 0.082 0.9467 0.0856 0.9813 0.0336 0.243 -0.0915 0.0741 0.0368 0.3151 0.0372 logdist 154     0.216 -0.1367 Table C.33 333 Machinery, Except Electrical Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 588 14.85973 4.166297 7.634337 23.93851 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 155     13.0103 Table C.34 333 Machinery, Except Electrical Correlations and Covariances logimports loggdp logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv logservus 1 0.8475 1 -0.0078 0.032 1 0.4598 0.7268 0.0807 1 logpopus -0.0154 0.0498 0.8931 0.1055 1 logexrate -0.2602 -0.1414 0.0465 0.0793 0.0457 0.8006 0.8082 0.2801 0.472 logservus -0.0172 0.0342 0.9642 0.0885 0.9499 0.0476 0.2903 logdist -0.0259 0.0974 0.075 0.3057 0.0832 0.2206 -0.0525 loggdpus logpop logserv 156     1 0.298 -0.2441 1 Table C.35 334 Computer and Electronic Products Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 635 14.98132 4.367618 6.309918 25.61189 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 157     13.0103 Table C.36 334 Computer and Electronic Products Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.8172 1 loggdpus 0.0447 0.0871 1 logpop 0.4254 0.6858 0.0764 1 logpopus 0.0495 0.1038 0.9017 0.0936 1 -0.2425 -0.1794 0.0264 0.0709 0.0221 1 logexrate logserv logservus logdist 0.82 0.7933 0.2344 0.2388 0.267 -0.346 1 0.0476 0.0958 0.9475 0.0869 0.9813 0.0256 0.259 -0.0711 0.0463 0.0264 0.3125 0.0297 0.2233 -0.1689 158     Table C.37 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Components Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max logimports 648 4.490916 2.11918 0 6.302619 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 159     13.0103 Table C.38 335 Electrical Equipment, Appliances & Comps Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.3009 1 loggdpus 0.0708 0.0841 1 logpop 0.0808 0.6845 0.0762 1 logpopus 0.0763 0.1029 0.9013 0.0933 1 -0.2542 -0.1863 0.0318 0.0703 0.023 1 logexrate logserv 0.3836 0.7911 0.2299 0.2353 0.2658 -0.3523 1 logservus 0.0722 0.0946 0.9473 0.0868 0.9813 0.0276 0.2568 logdist -0.111 0.0402 0.0283 0.3101 0.0299 160     0.229 -0.1717 Table C.39 336 Transportation Equipment Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 648 4.206718 2.273535 0 6.244167 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 19.4306 29.27214 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 161     13.0103 Table C.40 336 Transportation Equipment Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.2924 1 loggdpus 0.0648 0.0841 1 logpop 0.0807 0.6845 0.0762 1 logpopus 0.0654 0.1029 0.9013 0.0933 1 logexrate -0.109 -0.1863 0.0318 0.0703 0.023 1 logserv 0.3459 0.7911 0.2299 0.2353 0.2658 -0.3523 1 logservus 0.0656 0.0946 0.9473 0.0868 0.9813 0.0276 0.2568 -0.1757 0.0402 0.0283 0.3101 0.0299 logdist 162     0.229 -0.1717 Table C.41 337 Furniture and Fixtures Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev Min Max logimports 544 14.19315 3.610159 5.843544 23.44755 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 163     13.0103 Table C.42 337 Furniture and Fixtures Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.7553 1 loggdpus 0.0212 0.061 1 logpop 0.3922 0.6699 0.0564 1 logpopus 0.0244 0.081 0.899 0.076 1 -0.3179 -0.1905 0.0444 0.0765 0.0436 1 logexrate logserv 0.7503 0.7977 0.2243 0.2184 0.2549 -0.3534 1 logservus 0.0205 0.0723 0.9459 0.0696 0.9813 0.0463 0.2466 -0.1446 0.053 0.0132 0.3035 0.0159 logdist 164     0.225 -0.1484 Table C.43 511 Newspapers, Books & Other Published Matter Basic Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev Min Max logimports 160 12.14138 2.373729 7.646832 16.83724 loggdp 578 23.97549 1.863965 loggdpus 648 30.06781 logpop 648 16.12662 1.599653 11.12368 21.01467 logpopus 648 19.51439 0.023611 19.47779 19.54902 logexrate 643 3.265752 2.709218 -2.89864 22.62881 logserv 549 4.127796 2.641877 0 11.32446 logservus 576 12.52186 0.360845 11.83873 logdist 648 8.967749 0.541395 6.598359 9.677719 19.4306 29.27214 0.04693 29.98035 30.11611 165     13.0103 Table C.44 511 Newspapers, Books & Other Published Matter Correlations and Covariances Variable logimports logimports loggdp loggdpus logpop logpopus logexrate logserv 1 loggdp 0.6706 1 loggdpus 0.0933 0.2477 1 0.273 0.7102 0.1311 1 logpopus 0.0918 0.2781 0.9153 0.1453 1 logexrate -0.1017 0.0607 -0.0584 0.1204 -0.0259 1 logserv 0.6199 0.7743 0.4592 0.2178 0.5006 -0.121 1 logservus 0.1027 0.2654 0.9565 0.142 0.98 -0.0307 0.4867 -0.0875 0.024 0.0155 0.1598 0.0144 logpop logdist 166     0.0576 -0.0869 REFERENCES 167     REFERENCES Acemoglu, D., Antras, P., & Helpman, E. (2007). Contracts and Technology Adoption. The American Economic Review, 97(3), 916-943. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. Handbook of economic growth, Ed. Aghion P., Durlauf S. Amsterdam:Elsevier, 385-472. Affortunato, F., Ciommi, M., Crociata, A., & Mattoscio, N. The Performances of Italian Vertical Intra-Industry Trade in Cultural vs ICT Goods. Procedia-Social and Behavioral Sciences, 81, 200-205. Anderson, J. E. (1979). A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation. The American Economic Review, 69(1), 106-116. Anderson, J. E., & Marcouiller, D. (2002). Insecurity and the Pattern of Trade: An Empirical Investigation. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 342-352. Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2001). The Growth of World Trade: Tariffs, Transport Costs, and Income Similarity. Journal of International Economics, 53(1), 1-27. Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. (2009). Bonus vetus OLS: A Simple Method for Approximating International Trade-Cost Effects using the Gravity Equation. Journal of International Economics, 77(1), 77-85. Baldwin, J. R., & Gu, W. (2004). Trade liberalization: Export-Market Participation, Productivity Growth, and Innovation. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20(3), 372-392. Barney, J. (1991). Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120 Berthelon, M., & Freund, C. (2008). On the Conservation of Distance in International Trade. Journal of International Economics, 75(2), 310-320. Blum, B. S., & Goldfarb, A. (2006). Does the Internet Defy the Law of Gravity? Journal of International Economics, 70(2), 384-405. Bresnahan, T. F., Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. M. (2002). Information Technology, Workplace Organization, and the Demand for Skilled Labor: Firm-Level Evidence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 339-376. Bresnahan, T. F., & Trajtenberg, M. (1995). General Purpose Technologies 'Engines of Growth'? Journal of Econometrics, 65(1), 83-108. Brynjolfsson, E. (1993). The Productivity Paradox of Information Technology. Communications of the ACM, 36(12), 66-77. Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. (1996). Paradox Lost? Firm-Level Evidence on the Returns to Information Systems Spending. Management Science 42(4), 541-558. 168     Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. M. (2000). Beyond Computation: Information Technology, Organizational Transformation and Business Performance. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4), 23-48. Caballero, R. J., & Hammour, M. L. (1998). Jobless Growth: Appropriability, Factor Substitution, and Unemployment. Paper presented at the Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 48, 51-94 Chalmeta, R., Campos, C., & Grangel, R. (2001). References architectures for enterprise integration. Journal of Systems and Software, 57(3), 175-191. Choi, C. (2010). The Effect of the Internet on Service Trade. Economics Letters, 109(2), 102104. Choi, Y. J., Lee, S. Y., & Wildman, S. S. (2011) Why Do Large Markets Dominate? A New Look at Sources of the Large Home Market Advantage in the International Film. Paper presented at the 101st AEA International Conference on Media Studies and Communication. Clark, H. H., & Brennan, S. E. (1991). Grounding in Communication. Perspectives on Socially Shared Cognition, 13(1991), 127-149. Clemons, E. K., Reddi, S. P., & Row, M. C. (1993). The Impact of Information Technology on the Organization of Economic Activity: The "Move to the Middle" Hypothesis. Journal of Management Information System, 10(2), 9-35. Coase, R. H. (1937). The Nature of the Firm. Economica, 4(16), 386-405. Corso, M., & Gastaldi, L. (2010) Managing ICT-driven Innovations to Overcome the Exploitation-Exploration Trade-off: A Multiple and Collaborative Research Methodology in the Italian Health Care Industry. Paper presented at the 11th Int. CINet Conference, Zurich (CH). Costinot, A. (2005). Contract Enforcement, Division of Labor, and the Pattern of Trade. Mimeograph, Princeton University. Crandall, R., Lehr, W., & Litan, R. (2007) The Effects of Broadband Deployment on Output and Employment: A Cross-sectional Analysis of US Data. Issues in Economic Policy, 6, 1-34 Cuihua Shen, & Williams, D. Unpacking Time Online: Connecting Internet and Massively Multiplayer Online Game Use with Psychosocial Well-Being. Communication Research, 38(1), 123-149. Daft, R. L., Lengel, R. H., & Trevino, L. K. (1987). Message Equivocality, Media Selection, and Manager Performance: Implications for Information Systems. MIS Quarterly, 11(3), 355-366. David, P. A. (1990). The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical Perspective on the Modern Productivity Paradox. The American Economic Review, 80(2), 355-361. Day, G. S., & Hubbard, K. J. (2003). Customer Relationships go Digital. Business Strategy Review, 14(1), 17-26. 169     Deardorff, A. V. (1995). Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World? Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Dedrick, J., Gurbaxani, V., & Kraemer, K. L. (2003). Information Technology and Economic Performance: A Critical Review of the Empirical Evidence. ACM Computing Surveys, 35(1), 128. Dimelis, S. P., & Papaioannou, S. K. ICT Growth Effects at the Industry Level: A Comparison between the US and the EU. Information Economics and Policy, 23(1), 37-50. Draca, M., Sadun, R., & Van Reenen, J. (2006). Productivity and ICT: A Review of the Evidence. Centre for Economic Performance, London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK. Egger, P. (2000). A Note on the Proper Econometric Specification of the Gravity Equation. Economics Letters, 66(1), 25-31. Egger, P. (2002). An Econometric View on the Estimation of Gravity Models and the Calculation of Trade Potentials. The World Economy, 25(2), 297-312. Eid, R., Trueman, M., & Ahmed, A. (2002). A Cross-Industry Review of B2B Critical Success Factors. Internet Research, 12(2), 110-123. Erumban, A. A., & de Jong, S. B. (2006). Cross-Country Differences in ICT Adoption: A Consequence of Culture? Journal of World Business, 41(4), 302-314. Evenett, S. (2003). Do All Networks Facilitate International Commerce? The Case of US Law Firms and the Mergers and Acquisitions Wave of the Late 1990s.  Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 17(4), 520-537. Fink, C., Mattoo, A., & Neagu, I. C. (2005). Assessing the Impact of Communication Costs on International Trade. Journal of International Economics, 67(2), 428-445. Forman, C., Goldfarb, A., & Greenstein, S. M. (2009). The Internet and Local Wages: Convergence or Divergence? Cambridge, Mass: National Bureau of Economic Research. Frankel, J., Stein, E., & Wei, S.-j. (1995). Trading Blocs and the Americas: The Natural, the Unnatural, and the Super-natural. Journal of Development Economics, 47(1), 61-95. Freund, C., & Weinhold, D. (2002). The Internet and International Trade in Services. The American Economic Review, 92(2), 236-240. Freund, C. L., & Weinhold, D. (2000). An Empirical Investigation of the Internet and International Trade: The Case of Bolivia. Revista Latinoamericana de Desarrollo Economico, 2, 33-55. Freund, C. L., & Weinhold, D. (2004). The Effect of the Internet on International Trade. Journal of International Economics, 62(1), 171-189. 170     Griffith, R., Redding, S., & Van Reenen, J. (2004). Mapping the Two Faces of R&D: Productivity Growth in a Panel of OECD Industries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(4), 883-895. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Integration versus Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 85-120. Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1986). The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration. The Journal of Political Economy, 94(4), 691-719. Hamill, J., & Gregory, K. (1997). Internet Marketing in the Internationalization of UK SMEs. Journal of Marketing Management, 13(1-3), 9-28. Haveman, J., & Hummels, D. (2004). Alternative Hypotheses and the Volume of Trade: The Gravity Equation and the Extent of Specialization. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, 37(1), 199-218. Helpman, E. (1987). Imperfect Competition and International Trade: Evidence from Fourteen Industrial Countries. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 1(1), 62-81. Helpman, E. (1998). The Structure of Foreign Trade. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(2), 121-144 Helpman, E., & Krugman, P. R. (Eds.). (1985). Market Structure and Foreign Trade. Cambridge: MIT Press. Hiscox, M. J. (2001). Class Versus Industry Cleavages: Inter-Industry Factor Mobility and the Politics of Trade. International Organization, 55(01), 1-46. Hoffman, D. L., & Novak, T. P. (1996). Marketing in Hypermedia Computer-Mediated Environments: Conceptual Foundations. The Journal of Marketing,60(3), 50-68. Holt, L., & Jamison, M. (2009). Broadband and Contributions to Economic Growth: Lessons from the US experience. Telecommunications Policy, 33(10), 575-581. Hughes, A., & Scott Morton, M. S. (2005). ICT and Productivity Growth - The Paradox Resolved? SSRN eLibrary http://ssrn.com/abstract= 881797 Hummels, D. L., & Levinsohn, J. A. (1993). Monopolistic Competition and International Trade: Reconsidering the Evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 799-836. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2003). Government matters III: governance indicators for 1996-2002: The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 3106. Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., & Alchian, A. A. (1978). Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process. Journal of Law and Economics, 21(2), 297-326. Kretschmer, T. Information and Communication Technologies and Productivity growth: A Survey of the Literature. OECD Digital Economy Papers, 195. 171     Krugman, P. (1992). Does the New Trade Theory Require a New Trade Policy? World Economy, 15(4), 423-442. Krugman, P. R. (1979). Increasing Returns, Monopolistic Competition, and International trade. Journal of International Economics, 9(4), 469-479. Levchenko, A. A. (2004). Institutional Quality and International Trade. Review of Economic Studies, 74(3), 791-819 Hofstede, G. H. (1980). Culture's Consequences: International Differences in Work-Related Values. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications Lonsdale, P., Baber, C., Sharples, M., Byrne, W., Arvanitis, T. N., Brundell, P., et al. (2005). Context Awareness for MOBIlearn: Creating an Engaging Learning Experience in an Art Museum. Mobile Learning Anytime Everywhere.  Proceedings of MLEARN 2004. Bracciano, Rome: Learning and Skills Development Agency. Majdali, D. G. (2000). Trade Secrets Versus the Internet: Can Trade Secret Protection Survive in the Internet Age. Whittier Law Review, 22, 125. Malone, T. W., & Crowston, K. (1990). What is Coordination Theory and How Can it Help Design Cooperative Work Systems? Proceedings of the ACM conference on Computersupported cooperative work, 357-370 Malone, T. W., & Crowston, K. (1994). The Interdisciplinary Study of Coordination. ACM Computer Survey, 26(1), 87-119. Mansfield, E. D., & Pollins, B. M. (2009). Economic Interdependence and International Conflict: New perspectives on an Enduring Debate. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Martinez-Frias, J. (2003). Comment. The Importance of ICTs for Developing Countries. Interdisciplinary Science Reviews, 28(1), 10-14. Matyas, L. (1997). Proper Econometric Specification of the Gravity Model. The World Economy, 20(3), 363-368. McCallum, J. (1995). National Borders Matter: Canada-US Regional Trade Patterns. The American Economic Review, 85(3), 615-623. McLaren, J. (2000). "Globalization" and Vertical Structure. American Economic Review, 90(5), 1239-1254. Melitz, M. J. (2003). The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695-1725. Melville, N., Kraemer, K., & Gurbaxani, V. (2004). Review: Information technology and organizational performance: An integrative model of IT business value. MIS Quarterly, 28(2), 283-322. Moy, P., Scheufele, D. A., & Holbert, R. L. (1999). Television Use and Social Capital: Testing Putnam's Time Displacement Hypothesis. Mass Communication & Society, 2(1/2), 27. 172     Nunn, N. (2007). Relationship-Specificity, Incomplete Contracts, and the Pattern of Trade. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(2), 569-600. Pilat, D. (2004). The ICT Productivity Paradox: Insights from Micro Data. OECD Economic Studies, 38(1), 37-65. Quelch, J. A., & Klein, L. R. (1996). The Internet and International Marketing. Sloan Management Review, 37(3), 60-75. Rana, V. (2012). An Innovative Use of Information & Communication Technology (ICT) in Trade Facilitation in India. BVICAM's International Journal of Information Technology, BIJIT, 4(2), 492-495 Rauch, J. E., & Evans, P. B. (2000). Bureaucratic Structure and Bureaucratic Performance in Less Developed Countries. Journal of Public Economics, 75(1), 49-71. Riordan, M. H., & Williamson, O. E. (1985). Asset Specificity and Economic Organization. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 3(4), 365-378. Ryan, C., & Fleming, D. (2004). Digital Eco-Sense: Sustainability and ICT-A new terrain for innovation. Lab Report 03, ISBN 0-975-67431-5 Samiee, S. (1998). The Internet and International Marketing: Is There a Fit? Journal of Interactive Marketing, 12(4), 5-21. Samiee, S., & Walters, P. G. P. (1990). Influence of Firm Size on Export Planning and Performance. Journal of Business Research, 20(3), 235-248. Smith, A. (1937). The Wealth of Nations (1776). New York: Modern Library. Soloaga, I., & Alan Wintersb, L. (2001). Regionalism in the Nineties: What Effect on Trade? The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 12(1), 1-29. Solow, R. M. (1957). Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312-320. Stiroh, K. (1999). Is There a New Economy? Challenge, 42(4), 82-101. Stiroh, K. (2001). Investing in Information Technology: Productivity Payoffs for US Industries. Current Issues in Economics and Finance, 7(6), 1-6. Stiroh, K. J. (2002). Are ICT Spillovers Driving the New Economy? Review of Income and Wealth, 48(1), 33-57. van Ark, B., & Inklaar, R. (2005). Catching Up or Getting Stuck? Europe's Troubles to Exploit ICT's Productivity Potential. Groningen Growth and Development Center, GD 79 van Ark, B., Inklaar, R., & McGuckin, R. H. (2003). ICT and Productivity in Europe and the United States Where Do the Differences Come From? CESifo Economic Studies, 49(3), 295318. 173     Wei, S.-J. (1996). Intra-national versus International Trade: How Stubborn are Nations in Global Integration? : National Bureau of Economic Research, 553. Wildman, S. S., & Siwek, S. E. (Eds.). (1988). International Trade in Films and Television Programs. Cambridge: Ballinger Pub Co Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications: A Study in the Economics of Internal Organization. New York: The Free Press. Williamson, O. E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: The Free Press. Wong, M.-H., & Pellan, M. I. (2012) Trade Facilitation: The Way Forward for ASEAN and Its FTA Partners. Policy Brief, 2012-04. Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press. 174