one/7 .....wxz... xswuvx, ..Iuw. If)“. ...I “1.3.104”: a “I“... I I I. I...w .II...I..II OJ . III... «533:; A I‘.‘ ‘11.- If?” I: . ..2..... L..... I I ...... .. _. ..H/IWIII {Ava-a I. . .... ..III .4 .II .(....o1IJ. In. III I)... I’VIWJH I”4:.f1 .....In... 11..., If .2... ./Iz : “II/Hui... IWI I i. (I , III”..I.I ... I..I/ 4......2: ......I..I/..I./. .--”..quu.-- --- . H .I E... 15.5.1 11.5... .....J-IZ. ...»..n. ac. .rv~..( . . . I . . v II: ...3. ...... :4: Math; .9 nwfiv. tibiha. ......1 2n“. . . fiaégfi m"; a. JIxJaX..I.I.III..3W .95! (xi. . . .«u M. I. LIBRAP" Michigan State University NWWW This is to certify that the ‘ thesis entitled THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON THE BRAZILIAN ECONOMY presented by Eduardo Matarazzo Suplicy has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. an,” in Economics NCWfifl/i/JA. szm wt Major professor ABSTRACT THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON THE BRAZILIAN ECONOMY BY Eduardo Matarazzo Suplicy On 20 August 1968 the Brazilian National Monetary Council decided to follow a new system of adjustments to the foreign exchange rate. From that date, small adjust- ments would be made at short intervals in order to prevent the substantial differences between internal and external prices that characterize an inflationary economy with a pegged exchange rate. The minidevaluations constitute an attempt by policy makers to minimize the degree of exchange rate risk while avoiding the possible destabilizing effects of a free exchange rate. The purpose of the dissertation was to study the impact of minidevaluations on the Brazilian balance of payments and on the domestic economy. The main findings of the study were the following: The system of minideval- uations of the exchange rate at short intervals proved to have several advantages over the system of sharp devalua- tions at long intervals for the Brazilian economy. The main advantage was the greater stability in the relation Eduardo Matarazzo Suplicy between internal and external prices for those involved in the foreign sector of the economy. Thus, the exchange rate risk involved in export, import, direct foreign investments, and international loan operations was practi- cally eliminated. It was shown that Brazilian exports were posi- tively affected by the policy of minidevaluations. The regression analysis showed that this policy made exports of manufactures more responsive to changes in the level of real income and significantly more responsive to changes in the level of real remuneration to exporters. This latter occurred both through changes in the real exchange rate and changes in the level of fiscal incen- tives. Exports of primary products also were shown to be positively affected by the smaller fluctuations in the real exchange rate under the minidevaluations. The econometric analysis of imports indicated that a significant shift in the parameters of the import func- tion took place as a result of two causes: the lowering of import tariffs and the policy of minidevaluations. Imports became more responsive to income changes and especially responsive to changes in the real exchange rate adjusted for dollar inflation, tariffs, auction fees, and other trade barriers. Minidevaluations have had two major impacts on capital movements. First, they substantially diminished destabilizing short-term capital movements which previously Eduardo Matarazzo Suplicy had been harmful to the value of the cruzeiro. Second, along with other measures, they constituted a necessary Condition for the exceptional influx of foreign capital into Brazil that has occurred since 1968. The regression analysis of direct foreign investments indicated that they were reSponsive to profit opportunities--which were represented by the rate of growth of the economy--and to the decrease in the exchange rate risk caused by the minidevaluations. It was seen that the differential between domestic and foreign levels of real interest rates played an important role in attracting foreign loans and financing into Brazil. The portfolio approach to analyz- ing capital flows showed that interest differentials and the evaluation of risk, as determined by the exchange rate policy, political factors, and other events, were all important in determining the influx of foreign capital. By normalizing the expectations of economic units and by establishing the conditions for reasonable economic calculations in foreign exchange operations, minidevalua- tions have helped the government in forecasting and managing future developments with respect to the foreign indebtedness and reserve position of the country. Under minidevaluations, the exceptional growth in exports, imports, and capital flows was accompanied by a similar increase in service payments and receipts. Among service payments the items which registered larger increases were capital income (interest, profits, and dividends), Eduardo Matarazzo Suplicy transportation, and travel. Among service receipts, trans— portation and capital income increased most. The econometric analysis of price behavior indi- cated that minidevaluations have not constituted an inflationary factor. On the contrary, they may have aided the government in its pursuit of gradual stabiliza- tion of prices in Brazil. Finally, evidence was presented that minidevalua- tions had a positive impact on the growth performance of the economy. Qualifications as to the nature of this growth were made and suggestions for further research were cited. THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON THE BRAZILIAN ECONOMY BY Eduardo Matarazzo Suplicy A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1973 To Marta, with all my love. ii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I wish to acknowledge the help and encouragement received from the members of my dissertation committee, Professors Mordechai E. Kreinin, Chairman, Jan Kmenta, and W. Paul Strassman of Michigan State University, and Professor Clark W. Reynolds of Stanford University. I have drawn heavily on Professor Kreinin's knowledge of international economics and I am extremely grateful to his dedicated and detailed criticism of my work. I greatly benefited from Professor Kmenta's review of my econometric results and from Professor Strassman's critical remarks and suggestions. My lengthy discussions with Professor Reynolds and his encouraging and substantial comments were most helpful. I am indebted to William G. Tyler, Carlos Von Doellinger, Juergen B. Donges, Paulo H. Pereira Lira, Fernao C. B. Bracher, Joel Bergsman, and others who have written about minidevaluations and the foreign sector of the Brazilian economy. I wish to thank those friends with whom I have had vivid discussions and those who have encouraged me to proceed with my graduate studies. Among these are José iii David Langier, Luiz Carlos Bresser Pereira, John R. Moroney, Ary Bouzan, Alberto Oliveira Lima, Paulo Roberto Silva, Jorge da Cunha Lima, Manoel Whitaker Salles, and Antonio Angarita Silva. I am grateful for the encouragement received from Gustavo de Sa e Silva and Carlos José Malferrari, Directors of EAESP. I wish to acknowledge the generous financial support given to me by the Escola de Administracao de Emprésas de Sao Paulo, Fundacao Getfilio Vargas, the Ford Foundation (1971), the International Center for the Advancement of Management Education, Stanford University (1972), and the Coordenacao de Aperfeicoamento de Pessoal de Nivel Superior, CAPES (1973). I wish to thank Annibal V. Villela, Superintendent of INPES-IPEA and all those that I have interviewed to gather information. These will be mentioned by name in the text. I am grateful to Gary Ingvaldson for assisting me in the Computer Center, to David Allen and Elizabeth Johnston for their editing help, and to Irene Orr for her patience and goodwill in typing the manuscript. My greatest debt is to my dear wife, Marta, who has so enriched my daily life and who has encouraged me most, and to my children Eduardo and André, who gave me so many joyous moments along this journey. I am also iv grateful to my brothers and sisters for their encouragement and especially to Teté for her help in sending information. Finally, I am grateful to Papai and Mamae, and to Luiz and Noémia, for being such wonderful parents. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page DEDICATION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . .Viii LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiv LIST OF APPENDICES . . . . . . . . . . . . . xv INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 Chapter I. ANALYSIS OF FIXED, FLEXIBLE, AND SEVERAL DEGREES OF FLEXIBILITY OF EXCHANGE RATES . . 6 The System of Fixed Exchange Rates . . . . 7 The System of Flexible Exchange Rates . . . 10 Proposals for Greater Flexibility of Exchange Rates . . . . . . . . 16 Sharp Devaluations in Countries with Chronic Inflation: A Special Problem . . . . . 21 The System of Mini-Adjustments . . . . . 23 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 II. HISTORICAL BACKGROUND OF FOREIGN EXCHANGE POLICY OF BMZIL O O O O O O O O O O 36 The Role of Foreign Exchange Policy in Fostering Import Substitution . . . . . 41 The Post-August 1968 Period: The Minidevaluations . . . . . . . . . . 59 III. THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON EXPORTS: THE OVERALL EVIDENCE . . . . . . . . . 69 Effects of Fiscal Incentives for Exports . . 73 Effects of Minidevaluations on Exports of Manufactured Products: An Interpretation 89 Effects on Exports of Non-Manufactured Products . . . . . . . . . . . 100 Concluding Overall Evidence Concerning Total Exports . . . . . . . . . . . 107 vi Chapter IV. ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON INDUSTRIAL EXPORTS . . . The Method for Testing the Effects of Minidevaluations . . . . . . . . . Regression Analysis of Exports of Manufactures . . . . . . . . . . . Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . V. ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON EXPORTS OF BASIC PRODUCTS 0 O O O O O O O O O O O C The Model . . . . . . . . . . . . The Regression Results . . . . . . . . Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . VI. THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON BRAZILIAN IMPORTS o o o o o o o o o 0 Brazilian Imports Since 1968 . . . . . . Econometric Analysis of Import Behavior . . Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . VII. EFFECTS OF THE SYSTEM OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON SERVICES, CAPITAL MOVEMENTS, AND FOREIGN INDEBTEDNESS O O O O O O O O O O O 0 Effects of Minidevaluations on Capital Movements . . . . . . . . . . . . The Effects of Minidevaluations on Foreign Indebtedness and Accumulation of Foreign Reserves . . . . . . . . . . . . The Behavior of Services . . . . . . . Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . VIII. THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON INFLATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH . . . . . . . . . The Effects of Minidevaluations on Inflation The Effects of Minidevaluations on Economic Growth . . . . . . . . . . IX. CONCLUSION . . . . . . . . . . . . APPENDICES . O O C O O O O O O O O O O O BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii Page 119 120 123 142 143 144 147 150 151 153 154 170 174 174 196 203 215 216 216 237 252 258 345 Table II-3. II-4. II-5. III-1. III-2. III-3. III-4. III-5. LIST OF TABLES The Ratio of Brazilian Exports and Imports to Gross Domestic Product 1967-1971 . . . Brazil's Balance of Payments, 1967-1971 . . 1920- 100) o o o o Indicators of Brazilian Foreign Trade, 1967 (Indexes base:t 1939 = Free-Trade, Import and Export Exchange Rates, 1946-1967. . . . . . . . . . . . Real Effective Exchange Rate for Manufactured Product Exports, 1946-1968 . . . . . . Sharp Devaluations (1964-1968) and Minidevaluations (1968-1972) . . . . . Real Exchange Rate Adjusted for Dollar Inflation, 1968-1972 .- . . . . . Index of Remuneration to Exporters of Industrial Products via the Fiscal Incentives to Export, 1961-1971 (lst Quarter 1961:100), Tyler's Estimation . . Real Remuneration to Brazilian Industrial Exporters, 1961-1971 (in constant terms, that is, Cr$/US$ of the first quarter 1961), Tyler's Estimation . . . . . . Total Exports and Manufactured Product Exports of Brazil, 1953-1972 . . . . . Brazil's Total Exports and Exports of Industrial Goods in 1971 (CACEX Broad Classification . . . . . . . . . . Brazil's Exports of Manufactures to Different Markets 1965-1970 (US$1,000 FOB) . . . . viii Page , 4 , 5 , 38 . 54 . 58 . 61 . 64 . 74 . 77 93 . 97 . 101 Table III-6. III-7. III-8. III-9. III-10. III-ll. III-12. III-l3. IV-1. IV-2. IV-3. IVFA. Brazil's Total Exports and Shares in World Exports and in Exports of Less Developed Countries, 1946-1972 . . . . . . . . Export Values of Most Important Basic Exports of Brazil (FOB US$1,000,000) . . . . . Performance Indexes of Brazilian Basic Exports (Base year 1946 = 100) . . . . . Price Indexes of Some Basic Export Goods Dollar Price (Base Period: 1965-1967 = 100) Share of Major Basic Export Goods in Total Brazilian Exports 1964-1971 . . . . . . Brazilian Exports by Sectors, 1964-1972 (Index Numbers Base: 1964:100) . . . . Brazilian Exports by Sectors, Percentage Share in Total Exports 1964-1971 . . . . Brazilian Exports to Different Economic Regions, Percentage Participation of Each Region, 1964-1971 . . . . . . Variables Used in Regression Analysis of Exports of Manufactures. Definitions, Sample Means and Correlation Coefficients . Regression Analysis to Explain the Behavior of Brazilian Exports of Manufactures (Xlt)- Ordinary Least Squares Regressions with log Xlt as the Dependent Variable; 33 Quarterly Observations from lst Quarter of 1964 to 2nd Quarter of 1972 (2nd Quarter 1964 deleted due to Unusual Political Events). . . . . . . . . . . . . Test of Effects of Minidevaluations on Exports of Manufactures (Xlt) with a Distributed-Lag Model. Ordinary Least Squares Regressions with Log Xlt as the Dependent Variable . . Test of Effects of Minidevaluations on Exports of Manufactures (Xlt) with the Best Fitted Models. Ordinary Least Squares Regressions with log Xlt as the Dependent Variable . . ix Page 103 105 106 108 111 113 115 117 127 129 136 139 Table VI-l. VI-Z. VI-3. VII-1. VII-2. VII-3. VII-4. VII-5. VII-6. VII-7. VII-8. VIII-l. VIII-2. VIII-3. Page Data for Estimation of Brazil's Import Function (Model I) . . . . . . . . . 157 Data for Estimation of Brazil's Import Function (Model II) . . . . . . . . 158 Net Product Protection and Effective Protection, 1966-1971. Joel Bergsman's Estimation . . . . . . . . . . . 172 Differential Yields on Internal and External Securities Compared to Devaluation Rates . 178 Autonomous Capital Movements 1963-1972, US$ millions o o o o o o o o o o o 183 Differential Between the Real Return on a Bill of Exchange in Brazil and the Real Euro Dollar London Interest Rate . . 190 Differential Return on Domestic and Foreign Securities, the Rate of Growth of the Economy and the Inflow of Capital . . . . 192 Brazil's Foreign Indebtedness and Foreign Reserves on December 31, 1960-1972 . . . 197 Brazil's Net Indebtedness and Exports, 1960-1972, US$ millions . . . . . . . 200 Term Structure of Brazil's Foreign Indebtedness, US$ millions . . . . . . 202 Brazil's Balance of Services, 1960-1971, US$ millions . . . . . . . . . . . 211 Definitions, Sample Means, and Correlation Coefficients: Price Behavior Models . . . 225 Values of Variables Used in Models to Explain Price Behavior in Brazil . . . . 226 Application of the Quantity Theory of Money to Explain‘Price Behavior in Brazil and Examination of the Appropriate Lag in the Influence of Changes in Money Supply on Changes in the General Price Index. Ordinary Least Squares Regressions with pt as the Dependent Variable, 19 Annual Observations: 1954-1972 . . . . . . . 229 Table Page VIII-4. Test of the Effect of the Minidevaluations on Price Behavior in Brazil. Application of the Haberger Model with Modifications. Ordinary Least Squares Regressions with pt as the Dependent Variable; 19 Annual Observations: 1954-1972 . . . . . . . 233 VIII-5. Variables Used in Growth Models, Definitions, Sample Means, and Simple Correlation Coefficients; 12 Annual Observations: 1960-1971 . . . . . . . . . . . . 247 VIII-6. Data Used in Estimation of Growth Models to Test the Effect of the Minidevaluations . . 248 VIII-7. Test of the Effect of the Minidevaluations on the Brazilian Economic Growth. Ordinary Least Squares Regressions with 9t as the Dependent Variable; 12 Annual Observations: 1960-1971 . . . . . . . 249 A-l. The International Trade Policies in Brazil . 260 B-l. Brazil's Exports of Manufactured Products in Constant Dollar Value, Annual and Approximate Quarterly Data: 1964-1972 . . 279 8-2. The Real Exchange Rate (Wholesale Industrial Price as Deflator) and the Real Exchange Rate Adjusted to Dollar Inflation for Brazilian Exports: 1963-1972 . . . . . 282 B-3. The Real Exchange Rate (Wholesale Price for all Goods as Deflator) and the Real Exchange Rate Adjusted to Dollar Inflation for Brazilian Exports: 1963- 1971 (Tyler's Calculations) . . . . . . 286 8-4. Residuals from Linear Time Trend Regression of Brazil's Industrial Product in Real Terms--Annual Data: 1959-1971 (Base 1949:100) . . . . . . . . . . . . 289 B-S. Residuals from Linear Time Trend Regression of Brazilian Industrial Production (Proxy)--Quarterly Data 1961-1972 . . . . 290 B-6. Monthly Variation in the Real Exchange Rate for Exports (Percentage Change, Without Signs . . . . . . . . . . . . . 291 xi Table Page 8-7. Data for Estimation of Brazil's Supply of Exports of Manufactures Quarterly Data: 1964-1972 . . . . . . . . . . . . 292 B-8. Data for Estimation of Brazil's Supply of Exports of Manufactures, Annual Data: 1964-1971 . . . . . . . . . . . . 294 C-1. Effects of Minidevaluations on Exports of Manufactures (Xlt) Ordinary Least- Squares Regressions with Annual Data. Log Xlt is the Dependent Variable . . . . 300 D-l. Brazilian Export of Basic Products Other than Coffee . . . . . . . . . . . 307 D-2. Export Exchange Rate for Basic Products Other than Coffee . . . . . . . . . 308 D-3. Price Indexes of 28 Basic Products Products Exported by Brazil Based on the Average Price per Unit (US$/ ton) Base l964=100 . . . . . . . . . 309 D-4. Participation of Basic Products in the Total Value of Brazilian Exports (To be Used in Table D-S) . . . . . . . . 310 D-S. Construction of Price Index of Exports of 28 Basic Products Price Index Times Proportion of Participation in Total Exports . . . . . . . . . . . . 312 D-6. Monthly Variation in the Real Exchange Rate for Exports (Percentage change, without signs) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 314 D-7. Data for Estimation of Brazil's Export Supply Function of Basic Products Other than Coffee . . . . . . . . . 315 E-l. Case of Rapid Inflation and One Sharp Devaluation . . . . . . . . . . . 319 E-2. Case of Rapid Inflation and Monthly Devaluations . . . . . . . . . . . 320 xii Table Page E-3. The Official Import Exchange Rate and the Import Real Exchange Rate Adjusted to Dollar Inflation; 1955-1972 . . 321 E-4. Monthly Percentage Change in the Real Exchange Rate for Imports . . . . . . 331 F-l. Brazil's Import Coefficient Calculated in Current Prices, 1947-1972 . . . . . . 334 F-2. Brazil's Import Coefficient Calculated in Constant Prices of 1949, 1947-1971 . . . 335 F-3. Brazil's Import Coefficient in Several Periods . . . . . . . . . . . . 336 F-4. Brazilian Imports US$ millions (FOB) 1964-1971 337 F-5. Brazilian Imports: 1964-1971. Index Numbers Base Index: 1964 = 100 . . . . 338 F-6. Brazilian Imports by Groups of Products, Percentage Share of Each Group in Total Imports 1964-1971 . . . . . . . 339 F-7. Purchasing Power of Exports and Capacity to Import . . . . . . . . . . . . 340 G-l. Data Used in Estimating the Behavior of Direct Foreign Investments . . . . . . 344 H-l. The Productivity Residual in Brazilian Economic Growth . . . . . . . . . . 348 xiii Figure I-l III-l III-2 VI-l VI-2 VII-l VII-2 VII-3 LIST OF FIGURES The Equilibrium and the Pegged Exchange Rate Under Sharp Devaluations . . . . . . . The Equilibrium and the Pegged Exchange Rate Under Sharp Devaluations (Alternative Situation) . . . . . . . . . . . . The Equilibrium and the Pegged Exchange Rate Under Minidevaluations . . . . . . . . Profitability of Exporter Under Sharp Devaluations ProfitabilitycfifExporter Under Minidevaluations The Effects of Changes in the Price Level (Brazilian Industrial Wholesale-Price Index) and in the Official Exchange Rate on the Real Exchange Rate for Exports Adjusted for Dollar Inflation (United States Wholesale- Price Index) . . . . . . . . . . . The Effects of Devaluations of the Exchange Rate and of Fiscal Incentives on Brazilian Exports, 1960-1972 0 o o . . . . . . Total Brazilian Exports, Quarterly Moving Averages, US$ MillionsFOB, 1964—1972 . . . Brazil's Imports in Constant Cruzeiros of 1949, GDP in Constant Cruzeiros of 1949, and the Real Exchange Rate Adjusted for Dollar Inflation and Import Barriers . . . . . Brazil's Imports, GDP, Capacity to Import and Real Exchange Rate Adjusted for Dollar Inflation and Import Barriers . . . . . . Brazil's Balance of Services, 1947-1971, Current Dollar Value . . . . . . . . Service Payments, 1947-1971, Current Dollar Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . Service Receipts, 1947-1971, Current Dollar Value . . . . . . . . . . . . . Page 26 27 27 29 29 66 91 109 159 160 204 206 208 Appendix A. LIST OF APPENDICES The Battery of Incentives for Exportation . Exports of Industrial Goods: Sources, Effects of Minidevaluations on Exports of The Regression Results Manufactures: with Annual Data Exports of Basic Products: The Data, The Annual Average of the Monthly Percentage Variation (with no signs) in the Real Exchange Rate Data Used in the Analysis of Brazilian Imports . . Data Used in Estimating the Behavior of Direct Foreign Investment Evidence of Greater Efficiency After Minidevaluations XV and Data Problems The Variables, The Variables, and Measurement Problems Page 258 276 296 305 316 333 343 345 INTRODUCTION On 20 August 1968 the Brazilian National Monetary Council decided to follow a new system of adjustments to the foreign exchange rate. From that date, small adjust- ments would be made at short intervals in order to prevent the substantial differences between internal and external prices that characterize an inflationary economy with a pegged exchange rate. The minidevaluations constitute an attempt by policy makers to minimize the degree of exchange rate risk while avoiding the possible destabilizing effects of a free exchange rate. The purpose of this dissertation is to study the impact of minidevaluations on the Brazilian balance of payments and on the domestic economy. The main question to be examined is whether or not this system of adjustment was among the key economic policies that were responsible for the exceptional dynamism of the country's foreign 'sector and of the whole Brazilian economy from 1968 to 1972. In the first chapter the current state of the ciebate regarding the advantages and disadvantages of pegged and several degrees of flexibility in the foreign exchange rate will be reviewed. In particular, the advantages of a system of small adjustments within short periods of time as opposed to sharp devaluations separated by long intervals will be analyzed. Chapter II will present the historical background. After examining the role of foreign exchange policy in fostering import substitution in Brazil since the Second World War, the characteristics of the new policy of mini- devaluations will be described. The next four chapters will analyze the merchandise trade performance of Brazil before and after the adoption of the policy of small adjustments in the exchange rate. Chapter III will examine the behavior of Brazilian exports from 1964 to 1972. Quantitative estimates of incentives for exporters which will be used later in econometric studies and some recent studies of Brazilian exports will be discussed. In Chapters IV, V, and VI econometric models will be used to assess the effect of different systems of adjusting the exchange rate--sharp devaluations from 1964 to 1968 and minidevaluations from 1968 to l972--on exports of manufactured goods, on exports of primary products, and on.imports, respectively. An evaluation of the effects of different exchange :rate systems on capital flow movements, the foreign ijadebtedness position, and accumulation of foreign reserves vuill be made in Chapter VII. An attempt will be made to apply the portfolio approach to an analysis of capital movements. To complete the analysis of the foreign sector the behavior of the major service items from the late forties to the early seventies, but mainly during the minidevaluations, will be discussed. In Chapter VIII attention will turn to the domestic economy. Econometric models that explain price behavior and growth will be used to test the effect of minidevalua- tions on two major objectives of economic policy pursued by all administrations in the past decade: gradual price stabilization and acceleration of economic growth. Finally, Chapter IX will summarize the findings and conclusions of the study. The minidevaluations will be viewed in the larger context of general development strategy. Qualifications will be made and suggestions for further research will be cited. The ratio of exports and imports to the gross domestic product for the years 1967 to 1971 is shown in Table i-l to give an indication of the importance of the foreign sector in the Brazilian economy. Brazil's balance of payments is listed for the same years in Table i-2 so as to indicate the importance of each trade item vvithin the foreign sector of the economy. .mmumfiwumm wnmcaEwHoum« .mm .Nnma quEm>on mm .moHEmcoom manpcsmcou cum “Hammum 0p oocmm .xmudv .Hnma omwouuomxm .Hoflumuxm OHUHwEOO .Hflmmum "mmousom m.m H.mam.ma m.m m.mhm.ma «o.oom.m~m Huma m.h m.mom.ma m.m h.v¢m.oa «o.oom.~na onma m.m o.mmm.m o.w m.vam.m m.amm.ama mmma m.m m.mmm.m ~.m m.nna.m m.mmm.mm mmma o.m m.amm.q o.m n.4om.v m.mmv.an noma m Hmcoflaawe muu w HmcoHHHHE who choHHHHE who mow useuuso ca moo ucmuuso CH ucmuuso CA on muHOQEH mmflccmsouoz ou manomxm omflccocouoz Annoy uoscoum mo oaumm mo muHOQEH mo Genoa mo manomxm owumoEoo mmouw .anmaihwma uospoum owummaoa mmouw o» muHOQEH can muHOme cmHHwNmum mo ofluom chII.HIH mqmds TABLE i-2.--Brazi1's Balance of Payments, 1967-1971. U.S. $ Millions 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 A--Trade Balance 213 26 318 232 - 346 Exports (FOB) 1654 1881 2311 2739 2904 Imports (FOB) -1441 ~1855 -l993 -2507 -3250 B--Services - 527 - 556 - 630 - 815 - 978 Receipts 185 20 290 378 444 Payments - 712 - 761 - 920 -1193 -1422 C--Transfers 77 22 31 21 12 Receipts 107 75 82 87 94 Payments - 30 - 53 - 51 - 66 - 82 D--Balance on Current Transactions (A+B+C) - 237 - 508 - 281 - 562 -1312 E--Net Capital Flow 27 541 871 1015 1832 F--Net Errors and Omissions - 35 - l - 41 92 35 Surplus (+) or Deficit (-) - 245 32 549 545 555 Source: TFebruary 1972). Boletim do Banco Central do Brasil, 8, no. 2 CHAPTER I ANALYSIS OF FIXED, FLEXIBLE, AND SEVERAL DEGREES OF FLEXIBILITY OF EXCHANGE RATES Since the publication of Milton Friedman's classical essay, "The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates,"1 in 1953, numerous works have dealt with all aspects of the different degrees of flexibility in exchange rates.2 Although the debate still goes on, few countries have pursued policies other than that of fixed exchange rates since the advent of the 1944 agreement, following the rules of the Inter- national Monetary Fund. Therefore, few experiences have 1Milton Friedman, "The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates," in Milton Friedman, Essays in Positive Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953), pp.F157-203. 2The arguments favoring fixed rates, flexible rates, and several degrees of flexibility are summarized in Mordechai E. Kreinin, International Economics: A Policy A roach (New York: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich, Inc., 1971), Chap. 10, pp. 169-76, and are extensively discussed in M. O. Clement, Richard L. Pfister, and Kenneth J. Rothwell, Theoretical Issues in International Economics (Boston: Houghton, Mifflin Co., 1967), Chap. 6. A con- certed effort to find the best approach to greater albeit limited flexibility of foreign exchange rates is represented in George N. Halm, ed., arranged by C. Fred Bergsten, George 1N3 Halm, Fritz Machlup, and Robert V. Roosa, Approaches to Igggater Flexibility of Exchange Rates: The Burgengtock Pagers (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1970T. displayed the flexibility necessary for an empirical determination of how they would work. Since 1968 Brazil has realized small devaluations within short periods of time; this policy now can be examined and may well offer new insights into this field of discussion. The System of Fixed Exchange Rates As used here, fixed exchange rates refer to the adjustable peg that exists today under the articles of the International Monetary Fund. The present system of international monetary organization requires countries to commit themselves to maintain the foreign values of their curriencies within a narrow margin of a fixed par value by acting as residual buyers or sellers of currency in the foreign exchange market, subject to the possibility of effecting a change in the par value itself in case of "fundamental disequilibrium." Advantages and Disadvantages The existence of a single currency within a nation's frontiers has the following advantages: It simplifies the profit-maximizing computations of producers and traders; it facilitates competition among producers in cufferent parts of the country; and it promotes the inte- gration of the economy into a connected series of markets, .including both the markets for products and the markets :fior the factors of production (capital and labor). By analogy, fixed exchange rates similarly will encourage the integration of the national markets which compose the world economy into an international network of connected markets, with beneficial effects on efficiency and growth.3 This analogy, however, is defective. First, the factors of production, as well as goods and services, are free to move throughout a domestic economy, except for the existence of barriers created by distance and cultural differences. In the international economy, the movement of labor is in general restricted by national migration policies, and the movement of capital is limited by barriers created by national laws. Tariffs and other barriers to trade also inhibit the movement of goods. Those barriers prevent the system of fixed exchange rates from establishing the equivalent of a single international money in the sense of a currency the purchasing power and usefulness of which tends to equality throughout the market area. Moreover, if the ridigity of exchange rates is main- tained, not by appropriate adjustments of the relative purchasing power of the various national curriencies but by variations in the national barriers to trade and payments, it contradicts the argument for fixed exchange rates as a 3This analogy is based on the discussion by Harry Gw Johnson, "The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates, 1969," in Harry G. Johnson and J. E. Nash, U.K. and Floating LExchanges (London: The Institute of Economic Affairs, 1969), reprinted in Halm, ed., Approaches to Greater Flexibility, pp . 91-111 . means of attaining the advantages internationally that are provided domestically by a single currency. Second, acceptance of a single currency and its implications is not necessarily beneficial to particular regions within a nation. The pressures of competition in the product and factor markets promoted by adoption of a single currency frequently result instead in prolonged regional distress in spite of the apparent freedom of labor and capital to migrate to more remunerative areas. On an international scale, the likelihood of regional distress is substantially greater because of the previously men- tioned barriers to mobility of both factors and goods. Yet there is no international government, nor any effective substitute established by international cooperation, to compensate and assist regions of nations suffering through the effects of economic change occurring in the environ- ment of a single currency. It is commonly believed that the fixed-rate system exercises "discipline" over the nations involved in it and prevents them from pursuing "irresponsible" domestic policies. But this belief is a myth since nations have the option of evading discipline by using intervention or devaluation. The system obliges nations either to accept whatever rate of inflation or deflation emerges from the policies of other nations in the world economy or to employ whatever policies of intervention in international trade and payments they consider to be appropriate. 10 Defenders of the fixed-rate system argue for a solution along two complementary lines: "harmonization" of national economic policies in accordance with the requirements of a single world currency system; and progressive evolution toward international control of the growth of international liquidity, combined with "surveil- lance" of national economic policies. But countries have shown themselves extremely reluctant to accept the surrender of national sovereignty in domestic economic policy. This is due to the lack of an international mechanism for com- pensating those who lose out through adherence to the rules of the single currency game and to the fact that nations differ sharply in their views on priorities among policy objectives, especially with respect to the relative undesirability of unemployment and inflation. The System of Flexible Exchange Rates Under this system, fixed exchange rates are abondoned altogether. The values of all currencies are permitted to fluctuate (or float) in terms of each other in response to market conditions of supply and demand. ‘Advantages and Disadvantages The main advantage of flexible exchange rates .Aooa u amma “omen moxmcsHv 5mmalomma .opmue cmflmuom smeaflmmnm mo mnoumoflccH||.HlHH mqmde 39 .mmuem .aa .Am5ma .maoumcm Omm< “OHHmCMb mp OHmV moom Hammam .cmmcosam osvflasmm owamz "moasom m.m «.mma a.aa «.mma a.mmm m.mm «.mmm mama m.m a.¢ma m.oa e.oa~ m.mm~ m.vm m.oa~ mama m.a a.mma o.m m.ao~ o.ma~ m.mm m.~ma mema m.m a.ama e.m m.oma a.omm m.mm v.0ma amma m.w m.moa a.aa o.vma m.oma m.mm m.m- mmma o.m m.mma a.aa m.¢ma o.mma m.am m.mm~ mama m.m m.mma m.aa m.oma m.mo~ m.am o.am~ amma ~.m m.mva m.aa v.oma m.mo~ «.mm ~.mv~ coma m.m m.mma o.~a ~.ema o.-~ q.mm ~.mqm mmma m.m «.mma m.oa m.ama m.mm~ m.mm m.ma~ mmma m.m m.maa v.aa o.ema m.mmm e.mm m.am~ mmma a.m m.oaa m.m «.mma «.mmm a.vm m.oma mmma m.m m.moa m.m m.oma m.om~ m.mm «.mma mmma m.aa o.moa m.a o.oom v.4mm a.mm m.mv~ amma a.m m.¢m m.m m.ama a.mm~ m.om m.ama mmma a.aa m.am m.~a ~.oea m.o- m.~m m.~om mmma m.ma m.mm m.¢a m.o- m.ma~ m.mm o.mm~ amma m.aa m.~m e.m ~.aa~ «.mmm m.mm m.mma omma m.oa m.mm e.m o.oma m.mma «.mm «.mma mama m.aa m.em a.m m.mma m.a¢a «.moa m.oma mama «.Va a.mm m.m m.mma; m.aoa m.mma mvma m.omH 40 physical quantity of imports and exports after the 19305 was made possible by: (1) an improvement in the terms of trade during certain periods, particularly the late 19405 and first half of the 19503; (2) the flow of direct investment into the country. Foreign corporations have shown a continuously strong propensity to invest in Brazil as compared to other Third-World countries; and (3) the increase in foreign indebtedness, especially in periods when the terms of trade took a turn for the worse, as in 1962 and 1963. There was a decrease not only in the share of aggregate imports in Gross Domestic Product but also in the share of imports in the market supply of most commodi- ties. Import-substituting industrialization proceeded at a rapid pace. By 1949, most common nondurable consumer goods already had been substituted with domestic produc- tion. In that year imports amounted to only 4 percent of the total internal supply of such goods. Imports of intermediate products contributed 25 percent, while consumer durables and capital goods accounted for approxi- mately 60 percent. By 1959 the share of imports in con- sumption of durables, intermediate, and capital goods had been reduced respectively to 6, 12, and 33 percent. By the mid-19605 the Brazilian industrial system was excep- tionally integrated. The share of imports of intermediate and capital goods was less than 10 and 20 percent, respec— tively. Between 1949 and 1964 industrial production more 41 than tripled, while imports of manufactured goods decreased 30 percent.3 The Role of Foreign Exchange Policy in Fostering Import Substitution The key parts that exchange rate policies as well as tariff and nontariff barriers took in this process are described below. The factors that led to the adoption of these policies are related to world conditions of the last fifty years, which were not always favorable to trade expansion. The Great Depression adversely affected Brazil's export revenue, especially from coffee, discouraging fur- ther dependency on the foreign sector. In 1928 Brazil. exported some 15 million bags of coffee at about US 23 cents a pound; in 1931-1932 the same quantity of bags was exported at 7 to 9 cents a pound. Brazil, then, confirmed the belief that the industrialized countries suffer from unemployment and curtailment of production during a serious depression but not from a large reduction in prices; countries which are essentially primary producers do not experience a large reduction in production or employment, but their exports do undergo a sharp decline in price. The 1930 exchange rate of Cr$8.30 ("old" cruzeiros) to the dollar changed to Cr$l8.70 in 1939. Although the Second 3See Celso Furtado, Obstacles to Development in Latin America, translated by Charles Ekker (Garden City, New Yofk: Anchor Books, 1970). 42 World War favored Brazil's terms of trade in its generation of a heavy demand for exports, the possibility of export shipments was restricted, and a drastic rationing of imports was made necessary. This resulted in an increase in the foreign exchange reserves from about US$70 million to some US$700 million in 1945. The rate of exchange was unaltered, at Cr$18.70 per dollar. Of the US$700 million reserves, about one-third was in sterling and not freely usable; Great Britain declared its inability to pay except by transferring its capital investments.4 During 1945- 1947, the Brazilian Government, concerned with the level of coffee prices in international markets, kept the foreign exchange rate constant at the war period rate, even though price levels in Brazil had increased much more than in the industrial countries, particularly the United States. Experience had shown that partly because of inelastic demand for coffee the devaluation of the cruzeiro would cause a decline in international coffee prices. Also, the tariff system was based on specific prices per item and the rates had not been adjusted for the new higher prices. The interests of coffee-export groups pre— vailed over the interests of the new industries that had developed during the war years.5 4See Eugenio Gudin, "The Chief Characteristics of the Postwar Economic Development of Brazil," in The Economy prrazil, ed. by Howard Ellis (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1969), chap. 1, pp. 5-7. 5See Furtado, Obstacles to Development, pp. 115-16. 43 1947-1953: Overvaluation and Import-Licensing Controls Scarcely a year of liberation of imports and over- valuation of the cruzeiro exhausted reserves and increased foreign indebtedness. From June 1947 to January 1953, a licensing system was used to control both the level and structure of Brazil's imports. A system of rationing foreign exchange supplies to five different categories was instituted. Priorities were given to raw materials and semiprocessed products so that the productive capacity of the country would continue operating. Machinery for expanding national productive capacities was assigned secondary priority, whereas consumer items classified as "nonessentials" had the lowest priorities. Around 1949, the Law of Similars--under which imports of products "similar" to those locally produced were prohibited-- began to be applied and was enforced with gradually increasing frequency during the succeeding decade. The maintenance of an increasingly overvalued exchange rate, kept at Cr$l8.70 to the dollar, charac- terized the export policy in the period 1945-1953. The quantity and value of exports declined steadily from 1946 until the Korean War. From 1949 onward, exporters of certain products which were being priced out of the market were allowed to sell foreign exchange directly to importers of nonessential goods. This limited effective devaluation 44 for some export products was important just before and after the Korean War boom. The outbreak of that war, and the fear that it would become another world conflict, caused imports to soar from US$950 million in 1949 to US$1,703 million in 1951 and to US$1,702 million in 1952. Part of this expansion was financed by the export boom and part by compensatory financing. Over 55 percent of the increase in imports was in capital machinery and equipment. At the same time, however, many imports were difficult to obtain because of the war. In 1952, exports fell sharply, which aggravated the deficit in the balance of payments. These events strengthened the belief of the government that dependency on imports should be diminished.6 1953-1959: Multiple Exchange Rates, Taxes, and Bonuses The picture was significantly changed in the period 1953 to 1957. In January 1953, a free exchange market was established to cover financial operations and tourism. In October 1953, the system of multiple exchange rates with bonus and taxes was instituted.7 The official exchange rate was kept fixed as a base. On the export side, differ- ent rates were established: for coffee, the exchange rate 6See Joel Bergsman, Brazil, Industrialization and Trade Policies (Oxford: OECD, Oxford University Press, 1970Y, chap. 3. 7See Alexander Kafka, "The Brazilian Exchange Auction System," Review of Economics and Statistics, 38 (August 1956), 308-22. 45 was the official rate of Cr$18.36 plus a bonus of Cr$5.00, or a total of Cr$23.36 per dollar; for other products, the bonus was Cr$10.00, or a total of Cr$28.36 per dollar. The bonuses changed from time to time as did the adminis- trative setup. The average export exchange rate rise paralleled the domestic price level but with lags. The system lasted until 1959, and the quantum and the value of exports did not change substantially during the period. On the import side, import licenses were eliminated and replaced by auction sales of foreign exchange licenses. The monetary authority (SUMOC) allocated available foreign exchange among five different categories. Each auction corresponded to a specific category and was subject to minimal premia. Some imports, however, were not subject to the auction system. Among these were items for governmental agencies, wheat, newsprint, and petroleum products. The rate for these products was the official exchange rate plus eventual surtaxes which could be determined by the monetary authority. These goods accounted for about one-third of total imports. The other imports were classified into five categories: (1) inputs to agriculture, certain pharmaceuticals and inputs to the pharmaceutical industry, and some other essential commodi- ties; (2) essential raw materials (that is, for favored industries, almost all producers of intermediate goods); (3) other raw materials "essential" spare parts and equip- ment (again for favored industries); (4) fresh fruit and 46 other spare parts and equipment; and (5) all other commo- dities (most finished consumer goods). The same bias in ranking that characterized the licensing period (1947-1953) continued during the exchange auction period (1953-1957), but the magnitude of the price effects differed. The lowest exchange rates were applied to imports of capital and current inputs to agriculture and some favored industries; the next lowest were applied to other producer goods, and the third lowest rates were applied to finished consumer goods. The net result of the purchase and sale of foreign exchange went to the Fund of "Agios." Financial transfers and tourism were under the free market. Continuous inflation required revision of the exchange rates for maintenance of export profitability. In January 1955, four export categories were established, each with a different exchange rate level. Larger remuneration was given to products facing greater problems in continuing to be exported. In May 1956, the bonuses of some of the categories were increased. The functioning of the multiple exchange system led to increasing difficulties. Interest groups constantly complained and exerted pressure in the interest of changing import lists. Some domestic enterprises were discouraged, while the production of highly protected luxury consumption goods was stimulated. On the other hand, the monetary authorities were late in adjusting export exchange rates. 47 This was due in part to the decrease in the balance of exchange operations available to the Fund of "Agios" that occurred in each adjustment of the export exchange rate. This in turn resulted in a decrease in the extra budgetary revenue used by the government in its financial operations. Higher export remuneration was deleted in the case of some goods as a means of preventing increases in domestic prices. Foreign firms were given a Special incentive to invest in Brazilian industry by issuance of the SUMOC Instruction 113 of 1955. This regulation exempted foreign firms associated with Brazilian enterprises from the need to provide foreign exchange "cover" for the importation of machinery, an advantage denied to wholly Brazilian- owned firms. It was resorted to intensively during 1955- 1960 and figured importantly in the establishment of the automotive and other industries. Additional credit and exchange facilities were extended to domestic and foreign firms by the government after 1956 to promote industrialization. The subsidy given to the industries from 1955 to 1960 by such means was estimated by Eugenio Gudin at about 1 billion dollars. Consumers in general, people not living in the industrial areas, and agriculturists in particular bore most of the costs of industrialization. The monopolistic gains 8Conjuntura Econ6mica, 24, No. 1 (1970), 60-62. 48 resulting from protection, although substantial, were not included in this estimation.9 Until 1957, custom duties were regulated by the tariff of 1934 expressed in specific sums of cruzeiros. With inflation and with the depreciation of the cruzeiro after 1940, those tariffs became ineffective but were replaced by import licenses and exchange controls. In August 1957, a new law instituted ad valorem tariffs ranging up to 150 percent and reduced the number of import categories to only two: (1) general, for products the domestic supply of which was unsatisfactory, and (2) special, for most finished goods and for most producer goods which were available domestically. The exchange auctions were maintained. Fertilizers, newsprint, wheat, petroleum, petroleum products, and amortization and interest payments on foreign loans important for develop- ment were placed in a separate category. Here, a very low exchange rate, equal, in general, to the average rate for exports, was used. The system governing imports that was introduced in 1957 remained basically the same until March 1967, when the scheduled tariff was revised downward, and the multiple rates were eliminated. Some changes, however, such as restrictions and exemptions to limit or facilitate certain imports, were introduced along the way. 9Gudin, "Chief Characteristics," pp. 10-11. 49 On the export side, many products were transferred to the free exchange market in 1957. In December 1959, all products other than coffee, cocoa, mineral oil, and castor beans could be sold on the free market. The continuous inflation, however, together with occasional adjustments in the export rate, resulted in wide variations and uncer— tainty as to the export exchange rate. The real rate was characterized by an average (of absolute values) monthly variation of over 3.8 percent. The real rate drOpped 10 to 15 percent in several periods of three to six months. The rate for individual products varied even more, causing more uncertainty during 1953-1959.10 This discouraged exports, which, having totalled more than US$1,500 million in both 1953 and 1954, dropped to less than US$1,300 million in both 1958 and 1959. Exports of manufactured products (classes 5,6,7,8 of NBM--Nomenc1atura Brasileira de Mercadorias), however, starting from a relatively low level of around US$9 million annually in 1953-1954, rose to an annual level of US$12 to US$13 million in 1958-1959. This might have been due to occa- sional undervaluation--although with wide variation-~of the export rate for such goods during part of this period.11 loSee Bergsman, Brazil, pp. 35-36. 11See Donges, Brazil's Trotting Peg, p. 12. 50 1960-1964: Gradual Abolishment of Multiple Exchange Rates In March 1961, under some pressure and with advice from the International Monetary Fund, the monetary authori- ties moved toward the simplification and abolishment of the multiple exchange rate system. Under SUMOC Instruction 204, import exchange operations began to be effected at free market rates, and the subsidy on essential imports of oil, wheat, newsprint, and so forth, was drastically reduced. The special category of finished consumer goods, however, still was maintained with exchange auction. The exchange rate was effectively devalued 100 percent. In May 1961, export coffee operations also passed to the free-exchange market, although the government retained a "contribution quota" on each dollar exported to be applied in purchases of surpluses and in the infrastructure of coffee agricul- ture. Exports, including manufactured goods--sti11 less than 3 percent of total exports--performed relatively well in 1961. But the ensuing 1961-1964 period was marked by social unrest and political instability. Many restrictions again were placed on imports. Essential imports (oil, wheat, and newsprint) again were subsidized periodically. Inflation began to spiral, and devaluation again was allowed to lag behind price increases. To offset the effects of exchange overvaluation to some extent, exchange premiums ("bonecos") which varied according to product were used. 51 1964-1968: Unified Exchange Market, But Still with SharpgAdjustments In 1964, three distinct exchange markets and rates were in Operation: (1) the bank rate, used for official transactions abroad; (2) the so-called manual rate, used in the exchange houses for touristic purposes; and (3) the black or "parallel" market, used for unauthorized trans- actions. In May 1964, these different exchange rates were unified by governmental action. All export and import operations passed through the free exchange market, where the exchange rate was pegged periodically by the monetary authorities. But the period from 1964 to 1968 also was characterized by overvaluation and by sharp dis- continuities. Between December 1964 and January 1968, the cruzeiro was devalued three times, by 19, 23, and 18 per- cent, at respective intervals of 323, 454, and 325 days. This occurred in spite of the stated intention of the government in March 1964 to maintain a realistic exchange rate in order to eliminate distortions and to promote exports.12 Moreover, in August 1967, the monetary 12See Brasil, Ministerio do Planejamento e Coordena— cao Econ6mica, Programa de acao economica do govérno revolucionério 1964-1966 (PAEG), 2d ed. (Rio de Janeiro, 1965), pp. 47¥49, 131. The stated objective of the PAEG was to gradually establish a unified market for all exchange transactions with a free and flexible exchange rate, which would be given stabilizing support by the Bank of Brazil. Celso Furtado's Plano Trienal also pledged to maintain realistic exchange rates and to keep the same real level. See Presidéncia da Republica, Plano Trienal de Desenvol- vimento Economico e Social 1963-1965, (Sintese) (Rio de Janeiro: December 1962), p. 78. 52 authorities stopped selling dollars to all comers, which promoted the reestablishment of the black market. Exchange control was less tight in this period, however, than usual after the Second World War. In March 1967, the Brazilian economy moved toward import liberalization. Tariffs generally were lowered and the special category for imports was abolished. The very strict protection (tariff plus exchange rate premium) for these finished consumer goods dropped from the 180-220 percent to the 60-100 percent range.13 Tariffs on other products were reduced by approximately 20 percent. Important measures were taken during this period regarding the flows of capital and payment of returns. Laws 4131 (of 1962, modified in 1964) and 4390 and Decree 55,726 (February 1965) regulated both the remittance abroad of returns on investments of foreign firms and the manner in which foreign firms could raise short- and medium-term loans either with their mother company or with inter- national financial institutions. SUMOC Instruction 289, of January 1965, governed and promoted the ability of foreign firms to obtain short-term loans (up to one year) abroad. In.August 1967, Central Bank Resolution #63 made it possible for both national and foreign firms to raise short-term loans abroad using banks as intermediaries. 13See Bergsman, Brazil, pp. 36-37. After December 1968 the tariffs on many of those products were raised by 100 percentage points. 53 Beginning in 1964, the government began to promote exports through a series of incentives which will be des- cribed in detail below. Of key importance among them was the new exchange policy of August 1968. Some Detailed Estimates of the Level of the Real Exchange Rate in the Pefiodii946-l967 Taking into account protection against imports and implicit export taxes Joel Bergsman has estimated the free trade exchange rate and the real import and export rates for the period 1946-1967. These data are worth including for purposes of comparison with post-August 1968 events. The figures are shown in Table II-2, which includes index numbers of the real value of the free trade exchange rate and the real cruzeiro value of one dollar of exports or imports. The free trade exchange rate is an estimate of the rate which would maintain the balance of trade unchanged in the absence of tariffs, export taxes, and subsidies.14 The level of protection due to tariffs, exchange premia, and other restrictions and exemptions averaged 86 percent. The free trade rate during the period 1954-1964 and the implicit export taxes averaged 31 percent of that rate. Both protection and export taxes declined after 1964 and 14See Bela Balassa and Daniel M. Schydlowsky, "Effective Tariffs, Domestic Cost of Foreign Exchange, and the Equilibrium Exchange Rate," Journal of Political Econom (May-June, 1968), 356-59; and Joel Bergsman, Foreign Trade Policy in Brazil," unpublished study (Rio de Janeiro: U. S. AID, February 1971), pp. 56-57. 54 mca mma cma ma cm ccam 5mca NHH «ea cma mm cm comm mcca vma m5a acm mm 5m comm mcma mma 5ca cmm mm c5 cc5a vcca cad cca mmm mm Hca cmc mcma cma mca com mm mm cmm mcma mmH mca «mm cm m5 cmm acma caa mma cmm vm mm cam coma aaa cma mcm mm mm cca mmma am «ma cwm am mm mm mmma cm mma m5~ mm vaa ac 5mma ac mma cam 5m vqa a5 cmca mm cma ecm cm ac 5m mmma H5 ccH «ca an em cm vmma v5 mmca c5 mmca m5 amma mm cmma cm cvma mca mcma Had 5vca 5HH cvma Accauvmma How ovum ouch» wouuv “mum“ mummy oouu mo unmouomv Acc.awma\wuuv oumm oumm mumm mmxma uuomxm cowuomuoum ovum Meow uuomxm wmmaa mosh» MaomEH umoflHmEH uoscoam momma moan mosao> Hmmm no mmoacca .mcmaucama .mmumm mmcmcoxm uuoaxm can uaomsa .mcmasummumnu.mnaa mamas 55 .mmumem .amumm .mm .Hwnmam .soEmmaom cw commsomflc one mcoflumESmmo can meme :0 mcoflumufififlq .mEuomoH coamzlmaosaeom och mo muoomwo och 30cm 0p haso aonEooooiHHamc now one 5cca How came one .Amc .oz xoccm oomswcoom cuspGSncouv oowmoo mcflUSHUxo mooflam oammoaoc3 mo xoccfl ocu 5Q mouoa HocHEos ocu mamuoamop we cocaoueo oaoB mosao> Hmoa mo moxoch .ouoa ocmuu ooam may we cocfl>flc ouou uaomxo ocu mmoa .zuflcs mo copoasoaoo oao =moxou unomxm: .wuacs mmoa .oumn ocoau ooam on» an cocm>ac Amcoapmsoxo can mCOfluoHHumoa now owns mucosumsflcm cuflB .coau noncoam oeumoeoc co moxmu mood .cuaow on cam .momaoco umom .oHanm omcocoxo msam mmmaamp mcecsaocwv ouon uaomEH osu mo copoasoaoo we =cofluoouonm uoscoam: .po>oEoH ono3 .cuaom ow cam .moflcamesm .moxmu puomxo .mmmeHou we mucoemmm mo oocoamn on» ca Edflueaaflsvo saoucHoE UH503 coaca omcmcoxo one mo ouoEaumo am we =opma oconulooam= one .pocsaoca you one muaomxo oowmoo "wouoz .me .a .a.m maammfl.lomma .mmmam muamum>aac euoaxo .Domo "chomxov mowoflaom oUoHB csm coaumanMHHumsccH .Hflnoum .coEmmHom HoOH "oousom .UODCHUGOUII.NIHH mqmdfi 56 reached the relatively low levels of 20 and 15 percent respectively in 1967. The average product protection afforded to the industrial sector was only 30 percent in 1967. Years such as 1956 and 1961-1964 featured extremely high import prices, probably higher than necessary to prevent imports. The years of minimum import cost (1954, 1955, 1958, and 1960), however, also showed high protection-- in the 50-80 percent range. From 1964 to 1967 the export and import real exchange rates moved lower and closer together. i The real value of the export exchange rate coincided with that of the import exchange rate in 1945-1946, when the cruzeiro was substantially overvalued. This overvaluation is evidenced by the serious balance of trade deficit in 1946 and by the maintenance of the nominal export rate that was adOpted during the Second World War at a time when prices in Brazil had risen by 70 percent more than those in the United States.15 The overvaluation of the cruzeiro was continuously aggravated from 1946 to 1952 as the export rate fell 40 percent in real terms. From 1953 onward, the export exchange rate kept up with the rise in domestic prices in 15The term overvaluation, however, must be quali- fied. Import and export supply and demand elasticities, capital flow movements, debt service, the structure of import restrictions, and the like all would have to be considered in a study of an optimal or correct exchange rate level. See Tyler, "Exchange Rate Flexibility," p. 120. 57 terms of annual averages but still maintained the overvalued level. The exporter was further hampered by the variations which resulted from infrequent adjustments in the nominal exchange rate in the face of continuous inflation. The average month-to-month fluctuation in the real export rate in 49 months during the period 1948-1966 was over 5 per- cent. It was common for the real rate to drop 10 or 15 percent within periods of three to six months.16 The export rate of all exports (excluding coffee) followed a similar pattern of behavior in terms of levels and fluctuations; as discovered by Bergsman, this similarity was presented by the real effective exchange rate--inc1uding all bonuses and other gratifications--for manufactured exports. The effective exchange rate was calculated by dividing the current cruzeiro value of manufactured eXports by the dollar receipts for such exports on a yearly basis.' This sum then was deflated by the wholesale industrial price index to obtain the real effective exchange rate for industrial product exports. The data, as estimated by Tyler for the pre-minidevaluation period of 1946-1968, are shown in Table II-3. The real effective rate for industrial exports declined 28 percent from 1946 to 1952 (Table II-3). This 16See Bergsman, Brazil, pp. 37-54; and Joel Bergs- man and Arthur Candal, "Industrialization: Past Success and Future Problems," in The Economy of Brazil, ed. by Howard 8. Ellis (Berkeley: UniVersity of California Press, 1969), p. 33. 58 .soflumccsom momao> OanuoU may we oofleecoom mucussncou ca cocmflansm mofluom muouooficcH UHanoom Hmsofiuoz och mo ACOHpoUHMHmmoHo pace on xoccH ma xocsw oomnm HoHHpmscsH oaomoaozz .muoow couooaom .Hflnmam 0c uoaaouxm oaoawaoo .mmmm 60am opmc paomxm .5HH .m .HI>H oanoe .mmma undone .mcsum chmD cocaoamooaflfi :taflnoam CH manomxm coasuoomssmz mo coauOEOHm ocu cam COHuooamwmao>aQ uaomxm: .HoH59 .U EMHHHHZ oom "moousom ca.cm mcmca mm.ccmm mcca cc.Hm mmvm a5.a~cm 5cma mm.~m ac5c mv.amam coma c5.mm mccc ac.cama mcma mc.mm 5mam 55.aH~H vcma vc.am aa5a vc.amm mcca ~m.5m mmm ~m.mmm mmca c~.cm vvc cm.cv~ acma c5.cm va cv.m5a coca mq.vm ccm mc.c~a mmca mc.vm mmm 55.cc cmma m~.m~ cam mm.am 5mma cv.wm cca cc.mm cmma mc.am cma cc.5v mmma cc.mm «ma ov.cm wmma cm.mm cca cm.m~ mmca ma.am 5c cm.ca cha 5c.mm cc cm.ca Hmca «c.5m cc cm.ca cmma cc.5m cc cm.ma cema 5H.m~ mm cm.ca ccca cc.m~ «c cm.ca 5vma 5a.m~ mm cm.ma ccma 1mmma «0 meson ucmumcoo sac Iooaummmac 1mmcxmuoc ouom omcocoxm xoccH ooaum ouom omcocoxm Moo» o>auoommm aoom HowaumsccH odomoaon3 o>Huooumm .ccmalmvma .muaomxm poscoum counuoowssoz How ouom omcmsoxm o>fiuoommm Hmomll.m1HH mqmdfi 59 was less sharp than the 40 percent decline for all eXports (Table II-2), but the peak and bottom years were the same for both categories. Recovery from the low level in 1952 occurred with the exchange reform and devaluation of 1953 and the subsequent exchange policy. SUMOC Instruction 147 established a premium rate for textile exports that substan- tially increased the industrial export rate in 1958. The highest yearly average of the period was attained in 1960, just after the exchange reform of late 1959. Another decline took place before the 1964 exchange reform, which resulted in another peak, followed by gradual deterioration up to 1968. As seen in this dissertation, the effective real exchange rate played an important role in stimulating and discouraging exports. The peaks reached in 1960-1961 and again in 1964-1965 were accompanied by substantial growth rates (ranging from 55 to 85 percent annually) in the still very low level of manufactured exports. The Post-August 1968 Period: The Minidevaluations Since August 1968 the Brazilian government has been devaluing the cruzeiro by relatively small amounts at fairly regular six-week intervals. As already described in Chapter I, the exact timing and amount of the mini- adjustments, although expected by the public, have never been precisely known. In making the adjustments, the monetary authorities have been primarily guided by the difference between inflation rates at home and those abroad, 60 particularly, in the countries with which Brazil chiefly trades, and by the movements of interest rate differentials at home and in the principal international capital markets. Also taken into account are the current balance—of—payments situation, the amount of foreign reserves accumulated, and the foreign indebtedness position. Between August (exclu— sive) 1968 and December 1972, the official exchange rate was adjusted 35 times at intervals varying from 14 to 80 days. The average interval was 45 days, and the average rate of change was 1.5 percent. Table II-4 indicates that the total annual devaluations in the years 1969 to 1972 were about 7 or 8 percent less than the annual rates of inflation, measured by changes in wholesale prices of all commodities, in each of these years. The difference is partly due to external inflation. The difference between the domestic and external inflation rates, however, varies according to the price indexes used. From August 1968 to December 1972 the consumer price index rose from 100 to 218 in Brazil and from 100 to 122 in the United States.17 In the same period the wholesale price index for all commodities rose from 100 to 217 in Brazil and from 100 to 120 in the United States. On the other hand, during the same period, the industrial whole- sale price index rose from 100 to 194 in Brazil and from 17In terms of consumer prices for both countries, Index 64 of International Financial Statistics, Inter- national Monetary Fund, various issues. 61 ce.ma ec.ma eoq.a em mm.v mmm.a ma\~a mo.~a mo.ca aam.a mm mm.a mc~.e aa\aa mm.m mm.ma «ma.a mm a~.a mma.a m\oa oa.m mo.ma cm~.a am ma.a mma.¢ mmxm mo.m am.m~ ~a~.a mm oa.a mmo.v m\m mm.m mm.m~ mm~.a mm mo.a mmo.¢ ma\m ca.a a~.¢~ mmm.a ma oo.a mmm.m ma\m mm.~ mo.m~ mmc.m mm mm.m mom.m «\a om.o~ mama om.ma ~m.oa ~oc.a om mm.m mom.m m\~a mo.ma om.mm aom.a mm mm.m mam.m ma\aa am.qa aa.cm mm~.a mm om.m mmc.m m\m ma.ma av.am mma.ma emu mm.m mc.m m~\m ma.ma mam.ma mum -.m om.m a\a om.mm mmmm mmm.~m «ma mam.~ om.~ ma\~ om.mm Mmmm oa.mm coma am.o~ mam -.~ o~.~ ca\aa o~.am mama mm omm.a mmm.a mm\ma om.am mmma ImmauacoEEoo Amy Had no mooaam Ame Moo» Awe Aouou odomoaoczv ucounso oaowon omoconsm .ouv o o one can moo» ocu mo H\H co woo» oco GOHUMSHo>oU umoH coHuosHo>oc a m c m ouoa mamasc ouoaxwv oocam poomwo ca ouma omcocoxo, pmoa oocam cc.ammD Hom1mao acauoamcH ao>o omcmco omoucoouom mama ouoa omcocoxm .Am5malmwmav mCOHumsam>ocwcm2 can Amwmalvmmav mcofluosflo>o0 muocmll.leH mamma .ouoa omocoasm on» Oh uoommoa spas coumasoamo oHoB mouoa omcocoxo on» CH momcoco omoucooaom one .ooflsecoom ousucsflcoo ca cocmaansm moxoccH UHEocoom HMGOHuoz on“ mo ma cEsaoo .moaumcoEEoo Ham mo xocsfi ooflam oHMmoHocz Hoaosom ocu on maomoa oumu COHuonsw one .m5ma ou c5cH anm nonmmm Hmao>om .momuo> Omasuoo oooopcsm .moHEQGOUM manpcshcoo “ooasom mm.oa mm.oa mam.o mm mam.m ma.e ma\ma ma.m ma.m mma.a mm mma.m ma.e aa am.m mm.oa mma.a ma mmo.m oo.m oa mm.m mm.aa mao.a mm mmo.m mm.m m mmm.m mm.ma mm.o me mom.m mm.m maxm oo.m am.ma mom.a mm mam.m mm.m m\m mm.m om.ca mao.a ma mvm.m am.m ca\m mmc.~ mm.ea mmc.m om mmm.m mm.m m~\a ma.ma mmma ~m.ma ma.ma mmm.m am mme.m om.m oa\aa m ma.aa oe.ma mom.a mm mom.m ma.m oa\m ea.m mm.ca mm~.~ am moa.m mm.m ma\m om.c mm.ma aam.a mm mmm.m m~.m aa\c mm.e mc.ma amm.a «a mma.m ca.m maxm m~.m mm.ma oom.a am aa.m mo.m mmxm mo.a ma.va cmo.a ma mo.m oo.m m\~ om.om amma mm.ma mm.ma mmm.a am mm.a mm.e mm\~a me.aa ¢~.ma cao.a «a cm.a mm.q ma\aa mm.oa mo.ma mam.a me am.e mm.¢ «\aa ma.m mm.ma mam.a cm mm.a mm.a m\m mm.c mm.ma mmc.o «a mc.a ~c.v q~\m ma.c mc.~a amm.a mm No.4 mm.v oaxm mm.a am.~a mmm.a ma mm.a mm.¢ ma\m ma.m o~.~a mmm.a am ma.a oa.a om\m m~.a ca.~a am~.a ma aa.a mm.a a\~ om.am omma 63 100 to 117 in the United States a much smaller difference.18 The inflation differential for industrial goods is approxi- mately the same as the rise in the cruzeiro rate from 100 (Cr$3.65 in August 1968) to 170 (Cr$6.18 in December 1972). Table II-S shows the calculation of an index of exchange rate adjusted for both domestic and external infla- tion. Using the industrial wholesale price indexes in Brazil and the United States as the respective adjustment indexes, one obtains an index of real exchange rate adjusted for dollar inflation equal to 102 in December 1972 as com- pared to 100 in August 1968. This indicates that, for industrial goods, the cruzeiro has not become overvalued with respect to the dollar since the beginning of the mini- devaluations. Alternatively, using the consumer price indexes in Brazil and the United States as the respective adjustment indexes yields a corresponding index equal to 95 in December 1972 as compared to 100 in August 1968 (not shown in Table II-S). Therefore, in terms of all consumer goods, the cruzeiro has become slightly overvalued with respect to the dollar since the beginning of the minidevaluations. The difference between consumer prices 18The wholesale general price index for Brazil is Index 24 of the National Economic Indexes, Conjuntura Econ6mica, Getulio Vargas Foundation. For the United States the index is Index 63 of International Financial Statistics, International Monetary Fund, various issues. The wholesale industrial price index for Brazil is Index 51 of Conjuntura Econamica and for the United States is Index 63a of International Financial Statistics. 64 .pcsm waopocoz HmsoauocuoucH .moaumauoum Hoaocmcwm Hocoapocaoch .omc xoccH .mououm couaco on» mom .momam> oflawuou ooooccsm .MOHEQCOOM musucshsoo .Hm xoccH ”HHNon CH xoccfl ooaum HMHHUmnccfl oaomoaocz "ooasom m.moa m.maa c.mm ama Aomacma.c mm\~a ccH ccH ccH cca Accavmo.m mc\5m\m Avcxxmc Awe Amy Ame Aac mmumum cmuacc mmumum cmuacc ooa u mcma .msm Iooa u oc.ammc mama ca coaumaoca we» now lmv\1av mmma .msac umm who MOM coumsnpc xoccH oowum xoch ooaam Hamoum How ouom ouom omcocoxm Hmauumsch HmauumsccH ocu xoccH ooaum omcmcoxm ammm mo xmcca mammoaozz an cmumaomc mumm . amauumscca amaoamoo omcmcoxm mo xoccH oaomoaocz .mmmaumcma .coaumamca umaaoc now cmnmsnca mama mmcmnoxm ammmuu.muaa mamas 65 and wholesale industrial prices can be explained in terms Of growth Of output per capita. During periods of high rates Of economic growth, the leading sectors have a higher increase in productivity and, in general, tend to have relatively lower increases in prices than other sectors. Rapid increases in real wages in the high growth sector, mainly industry, lead to increases in the cost of services and other goods to final consumers, which affects the consumer price index. This explains why during the period 1968-1972, years of very high economic growth in Brazil, the prices in industry increased relatively less than the consumer price index.19 Stricter price guide- lines for industrial goods than for other goods also account for the differential. Figure II-l shows that the real exchange rate adjusted for dollar inflation has fluctuated only mildly around the value Of 100--the base index for August 1968-- during the whole period of minidevaluations. In this case the Brazilian wholesale price index for industrial goods and the United States wholesale price index for all commo- dities were used as the respective adjustment indexes for domestic and external inflation. The calculations for the index of Figure II-l are shown in Table B-2 of Appendix B. 198ee Ronald I. McKinnon, Monetary Theory and Controlled Flexibility in the Foreign Exchanges, Essays in International Finance, NO. 84 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1971), pp. 21-23. Jr. —- 66 Figure II-l.--The Effects Of Changes in the Price Level (Brazilian Industrial Wholesale-Price Index) and in the Official Exchange Rate on the Real Exchange Rate for Exports Adjusted for Dollar Inflation (United States Wholesale- Price Index). 67 coma -roa a5ca c5ma coca coca 5cca coma _ F moma L, — voma *5 _ .r_ F, _ _ _ —, _ _ _ b _ _ _ _ _ _ P — a .1 1 _ r _ , C [r 1 1 a (r P1. I8 12 l8 Tom Taaa .loaa rIowa Iona . Iooa " aama umamsa "mmmm xuvcac Sama 2 $33. 85a 8333: .338 8. @3334 lo: ouom omcocoxm auom onu «0 xopca aasucoz cma fi# macauonam>ocacaa mo coauom 68 Certainly for industrial goods and somewhat less so for other goods, the application of the minidevaluations has arrested the recurrent decline in the real exchange rate that occurred prior to August 1968. As will be seen in the following chapters, this phenomneon had important effects on the Brazilian economy. CHAPTER III THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON EXPORTS: THE OVERALL EVIDENCE The Brazilian system Of minidevaluations Of the exchange rate provided the exporter with the prospect of a relatively stable relationship between internal produc- tion costs and world market prices. Because the partici- pation Of Brazil's nontraditional exports in the world market is very limited, the country's position is close to that of a perfect competitor,1 and the demand for those products is highly elastic. Therefore, prior to August 1968, when the cruzeiro was devalued every 12 to 15 months, nontraditional exports yielded more or less stable dollar prices in the international markets, cruzeiro returns remained constant for prolonged periods, and costs of 1In fact, the nature of the position Of potential exporters Of manufactured products should be qualified. Most of them are not small firms without connections in the world market but, rather, are firms which are affiliated with multinational companies. In most cases the decision whether or not to export is made by the mother firm out- side Of Brazil. With this problem in mind, the Brazilian government has Offered several incentives for multinational companies to export from Brazil. A very interesting study on this matter is one by Fernando Fajnzylber, Sistema Industrial e Exportacao de Manufacturados, Anélise da Experigncia Brasileira (Rio de Janeiro: IPEA/INPES, 1971). 69 70 inputs and wages rose steadily. The new exchange policy corrected this situation of large fluctuations in the profit margins Of export sales. The international prices of the more traditional products such as coffee, cocoa, cotton, and sugar f1uc- tuate widely in world markets. This made the virtual elimination of exchange rate risk, one of the reasons for fluctuations in cruzeiro prices, significant for exporters of such products. The minidevaluations also represented greater stability in the level of incentives for exporters. Various entrepreneurs stressed in interviews with the author in August 1972 (and confirmed by other writersz) that the system of minidevaluations, coupled with the whole battery of fiscal, financial, and other government- supported incentives, was largely responsible for the extraordinary growth of Brazilian exports from 1968 to 1972. While this growth was concentrated mainly in manufactures, it also featured other products, both nontraditional and traditional. 2See Carlos von Doellinger, Hugo de Barros Castro Faria, Jose Eduardo Carvalho Pereira, and Maria Helena T. T. Horta, Ex orta Oes dinamicas brasileiras, IPEA (Rio de Janeiro: 1971); Fajnzylber, Sistema Industrial e Exportacao de Manufaturados; Tyler,i"Exchange RateiFlexi- bility"; Donges, Brazil's Trotting Peg; and Helmut Hesse, "Promotion of Manufactured Exports as Development Strategy Of Semi-Industrialized Countries: The Brazilian Case," Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv. Review of World Economics, 108, NO. 2 (19725, 234-55. 71 Directors of some of the leading exporting firms, those which deal with traditional products such as coffee, cocoa, and cotton, and those which deal with nontraditional products, such as manufactured and other primary goods, all unanimously agreed that the system of minidevaluations constituted a sine qua non for the high performance Of the export sector.3 Tyler also interviewed manufactures about the fiscal, financial, and other types of incentives for exportation. All respondents stressed the importance of minidevaluations in diminishing entrepreneurial risk by enabling them to make more accurate predictions of export profitability.4 Exporters also regard the exchange policy as a sign of government commitment to the promotion of exports. Thus, previous uncertainty as to the govern- ment's intentions has been substantially reduced. The new minidevaluation policy permits the exporters to make 3Interviews conducted by the author in August Of 1972 with Mr. Horacio Coimbra, Director, Cafe Cacique (largest exporter of manufactured foods and of soluble coffee); Mr. Laerte Setubal, Director, Duratex SA (largest exporter Of processed wood boards); the Superintendent of SAMBRA, Sociedade Algodoeira de Nordeste (largest exporter of traditional agricultural products); Mr. Eugenio Staub, Director, Staub SA (important medium-sized exporter of electronic parts); Mr. Luiz M. Suplicy Hafers, Director, Escritorio Suplicy (traditional export agent of coffee, cotton, and other agricultural products); and others. 4See Tyler, "Exchange Rate Flexibility," p. 19; and Hesse, "Promotion Of Manufactured Exports," p. 238. See also William G. Tyler, "Fiscal Incentives for Manu- factured Export Promotion: The Brazilian Case," Working Paper 72-01, Department of Economics, University of Florida. 72 long-range investment plans and marketing arrangements for selling his products in international markets. At the same time, the purchaser is assured of greater dependability of supply.5 In 1964 the total export revenue Of Brazil rose from the stagnant level of about US$1.4 billion at which ’ it had remained since 1947. From 1964 to 1967 export per- formance improved only moderately, but with the introduction of minidevaluations exports attained very high growth rates, 5In 1965 the author became directly familiar with the problem Of dependability Of supply and the on-again- Off-again nature of export profitability while working with the Escritorio Suplicy which was trying to sell some Brazilian manufactured goods abroad. Some fiscal incentives already were in effect. These mainly were exemption from direct payment of the sales tax (IVC--Imposto de Vendas e ConsignacOes), later modified into the value-added ICM tax, which was put into effect in August 1964, and exemption from payment of the tax on industrial products (IPI-- Imposto sobre Produtos Industrializados), introduced in August 1965. The government's slogan was: "Exporting is the Solution." Escritorio Suplicy was then export agent for several textile firms which wanted to sell cotton yarns and fabrics abroad, for a firm which produced canvas shoes, and for another which marketed paper-fiber boards. Although a 90 percent inflation had occurred during 1964, the firms wanted to start exporting after the 57 percent devaluation of the exchange rate in December of that year. They pro- vided price lists in the beginning of 1965 which were sent to possible purchasers abroad. But inflation during 1965 was 52 percent in Brazil. By the middle of the year the firms needed to readjust their price lists because Of increased costs. In November 1965 the author visited poten- tial customers in the United States for a month. On 16 November the cruzeiro was devalued 20 percent,and new sub- stantial price adjustments were made possible. Potential buyers, however, were inclined to avoid long-run commitments with suppliers whose price lists were subject to uncertain and drastic changes. The situation was different for primary products like coffee and cotton because purchasers of such commodities are used to wide fluctuations in market prices. 73 and Brazil's export revenue reached a total of $2.9 billion in 1971 and $4.0 billion in 1972. The various Brazilian governments during the past decade have presented a battery of fiscal, financial, and institutional incentives for exporters, particularly those involved with industrial products. The incentives were intensified after 1968, which markedly affected the profitability of exports. A detailed examination of these incentives is presented in Appendix A. Estimates of their magnitude are essential in order to determine the effect Of the exchange rate policy as precisely as possible. Effects of Fiscal Incentives for Exports William Tyler, Helmut Hesse, and others have estimated the effects Of fiscal incentives on exports, mainly of manufactured products. Their results are dis- cussed below. T ler's Estimates of Fiscal’Incentives Table 111-1 shows the 1961-1971 index of remunera- tion to exporters of industrial products through fiscal incentives as calculaged by Tyler. The index indicates how much more a firm would obtain if it were to sell its product abroad rather than in the domestic market. Excluded from this table are the impacts Of drawback provisions and of less important tax exemptions such as relief from the 74 TABLE III-1.--Index of Remuneration to Exporters of Indus- trial Products via the Fiscal Incentives to Export,a 1961-1971 (lst Quarter l961=100), Tyler's Estimation. Tax on Income Financial Year I.P.I. I.C.M. Tax Operations Total 1961 I 100 100 100 100 100 II 100 100 100 100 100 III 100 100 100 100 100 IV 100 100 100 100 100 1962 I 100 100 100 100 100 II 100 100 100 100 100 III 100 100 100 100 100 IV 100 100 100 100 100 1963 I 100 100 100 100 100 II 100 100 100 100 100 III 100 100 100 100 100 IV 100 100 100 100 100 1964 I 100 100 100 100 100 II 100 100 100 100 100 III 100 101 100 100 101 IV 100 103 100 100 103 1965 I 100 103 100 100 103 II 100 103 100 101 104 III 105.02 103 100 101 109.02 IV 115.07 103 100 101 119.07 1966 I 115.07 103 100 101 119.07 II 115.07 103 100 101 119.07 III 115.07 103 100 101 119.07 IV 115.07 103 100 101 119.07 1967 I 115.07 103.10 102.8 101 121.97 II 115.07 109.30 104.2 101 129.57 III 115.07 109.30 104.2 101 129.57 IV 115.07 109.30 104.2 101 129.57 1968 I 115.07 109.30 104.2 101 129.57 II 115.07 109.30 104.2 101 129.57 III 121.24 109.30 104.2 101 135.74 IV 121.24 109.30 104.2 101 135.74 1969 I 121.24 109.30 104.2 101 135.74 II 121.24 109.30 104.2 101 135.74' III 127.41 109.30 104.2 101 141.90 IV 127.41 109.30 104.2 101 141.90 75 TABLE III-1.--Continued. Tax on 1 Income Financial Year I.P.I. I.C.M. Tax Operations Total 1970 I 127.41 109.30 104.2 101 141.90 II 127.41 109.30 104.2 101 141.90 III 127.41 109.30 104.2 101 141.90 IV 127.41 109.30 104.2 101 141.90 1971 I 127.41 117.0 104.2 101 149.61 II 127.41‘ 117.0 104.2 101 149.61 Sources: Calculated from data supplied by the Ministry of Finance and CACEX; William G. Tyler, "Fiscal Incentives for Manufactured Export Promotion: The Brazilian Case," Working Paper 72-01, Department of Economics, University of Florida. aPercentages are calculated from the domestic price base = 100. The term remuneration is used to mean the differential between domestic prices and possible export prices. See Appendix A for the description of all incentives. tax on combustibles, lubricants, and electric energy, as well as other governmental fees. Adding up the tax incentives related to the tax on industrialized products (IPI), tax on circulation of goods (ICM), income tax, and tax on financial Operations (see also Appendix A), reveals that the differential in remuneration between domestic and foreign markets became important for the first time in the last quarter of 1965, when it amounted to an average of 19 percent. This increased to a 35.74 percent differential in the second half of 1968. By the beginning Of 1971, exporters could sell their products for an external price 76 of about 50 percent less than the domestic price and still Obtain the same level Of remuneration. Tyler also has calculated a real effective exchange rate for Brazilian manufactured exports adjusted for dollar inflation in order to compare that rate with the increase in local currency remuneration due to fiscal incentives. The Brazilian wholesale industrial price index was used to deflate the effective exchange rate, and the U.S. wholesale price index was employed to adjust for dollar inflation. Table III-2 shows that, even after accounting for dollar inflation, the Brazilian export exchange rate (in terms of cruzeiros per dollar) in real terms has fallen since 1961. A sharp decline occurred between 1961 and the first quarter of 1964, and a slight one occurred between the overthrow of Joao Goulart in 1964 and 1968. After the initiation of the minidevalua- tions in August 1968, however, the real effective exchange rate as adjusted to the dollar inflation has remained at approximately the same level and has fluctuated only moderately. The combination of the real effective exchange rate as adjusted to dollar inflation with the fiscal incentives for export gives the rate of real effective remuneration. Table III-2 shows that this rate has increased approximately 27 percent since the second quarter of 1964. This increase has been due to the fiscal incentives which have more than Offset the decline in the real exchange rate. 77 TABLE III-2.--Real Remuneration to Brazilian Industrial Exporters, 1961-1971 (in constant terms, that is, Cr$/US$ Of the first quarter 1961), Tyler's Estimation. Dollar Inflation Adjusted Real Index Of Remuneration to Industrial Exporters via the Rate of Real Effective Exchange Fiscal Incentives Effective Ratea for Export Remunerationc (X2) (X3) 1961 I .201 100.00 .201 II .223 100.00 .223 III .196 100.00 .196 IV .214 100.00 .214 1962 I .209 100.00 .209 II .200 100.00 .200 III .216 100.00 .216 IV .218 100.00 .218 1963 I .161 100.00 .161 II .170 100.00 .170 III '.179 100.00 .179 IV .164 100.00 .164 1964 I .160 100.00 .160 II .211 100.00 .211 III .191 101.00 .193 IV .211 103.00 .217 1965 I .205 103.00 .211 II .198 104.00 .206 III .199 109.02 .217 IV .202 119.07 .241 1966 I .202 119.07 .241 II .192 119.07 .229 III .188 119.07 .224 IV .177 119.07 .211 1967 I .177 121.97 .216 II .184 129.57 .238 III .182 129.57 .236 IV .178 129.57 .231 1968 I .184 121.57 .238 II .177 129.57 .229 III .173 135.74 .235 IV .183 135.74 .248 78 TABLE III-2.--Continued. Index of Remuneration to Dollar Inflation Industrial Adjusted Real Exporters via the Rate Of Real Effective Exchange Fiscal Incentives EffeCtlv? c Ratea for Exportb Remunerat1on (82) (X3) 1969 I .186 135.74 .252 II .190 135.74 .258 III .189 141.90 .268 IV .192 141.90 .272 1970 I .195 141.90 .277 II .192 141.90 .272 III .189 141.90 .268 IV .189 141.90 .268 1971 I .189 149.61 .282 II .186 149.61 .279 Sources: Ministerio da Fazenda, Boletim do Comercio ' Exterior, various issues; Con'untura EconOmica; Federal Reserve Bulletin; William G. Tyler, "Fiscal Incentives for Manufactured Export Promotion: The Brazilian Case," Working Paper 72-01, Department of Economics, University Of Florida. aInstead Of using the nominal exchange rate to calculate the real exchange rate, an effective exchange rate for manufactured exports was estimated and employed. The effective exchange rate incorporates exporter earnings from varying export bonuses which were widespread before 1963. It was calculated by dividing the cruzeiro value of manufactured exports by their dollar value. All values are in (new) cruzeiros. bSee Table 111-1 above. cThe real effective remuneration to manufactured exporters is calculated as: 79 Hesse's Estimates of Fiscal Incentives Helmut Hesse, in a manner similar to Tyler's, also has estimated the impact Of fiscal incentives on the remuneration of exporters. His calculations are designed to answer the following question: what export price (in Cr$) would yield the same net profit as a price (including all taxes) on the domestic market, if all fiscal incentives are taken into account? Whereas Tyler calculated the impact of fiscal incentives on export remuneration from 1961 to 1971, Hesse has done the same for only one period, May 1971. He found that the combined fiscal incentives, on the average, permitted the export price to be reduced to 64 percent Of the domestic market price without reducing net profits, as of May 1971. (These are approximately the same results found by Tyler, who estimated an almost 50 percent [49.61%] differential in remuneration between the domestic and foreign market during the first semester of 1971. That is, under Tyler's estimation, the combined fiscal incentives for exports of manufactures [excluding the drawback] permitted the export price to be reduced to 66.6 percent of the domestic market price without reducing net profits.) The variances among the 43 manufacturing sectors estimated by Hesse, however, are large. They range from 16 percent for tobacco products (which have extremely high indirect taxes» to 42 percent for beverages, to 59 percent for textiles and domestic appliances, and 80 to 71-75 percent for meat, dairy products, cereals, other foods, fats and Oils, sacks, bags and linen goods, lumber, chemicals, metal castings, and airplanes. The breakdown for the 43 sectors of the various incentives as of May 1971, on the average, is the follow- ing. First, the IPI and ICM tax credits (subsidies) amounted to 14.7 percent of the fob value of exports. Because of these credits, an exporter could sell for a price equal to 87 percent of the domestic market price and receive the same net profit. Second, exemptions from indirect taxes on export products and on inputs in export production (drawback included) made it possible to reduce the export price to 76 percent of the domestic market price (84 percent if no rebate from the ICM paid on pre- vious stages Of production) without reducing net profit. The 24 percent differential between the export and domestic price is composed Of an 8 percent IPI exemption, a 7 per- cent ICM exemption, an 8 percent rebate of ICM on previous stages of production, an 0.6 percent drawback, and 0.4 percent reduction from other indirect taxes. Third, the variance Of the value of indirect tax credits and exemptions is quite large between the industrial sectors due to different tax levels. Finally, the corporate income tax exemption amounts to a subsidy of 3.3 percent of the domestic market price. 81 Tyler's Econometric Analysis Of the Fiscal Incentives for Export and the Exchange Rate Level Tyler specified a regression model in which the dependent variable is Brazil's manufactured exports and the independent variables are the fiscal incentives, the real exchange rate, a proxy for capacity utilization, and world demand. This model presents an identification problem, but given that Brazil's share in total world manufactures exports is less than 1 percent, one may assume that the demand for Brazil's industrial exports is perfectly elastic. Therefore, the model essentially represents an export supply function. Increases in the real exchange rate in fiscal incentives or in world trade shift the demand curve upward. The proxy for capacity utilization affects supply. Using quarterly data from 1961 to 1970, the basic regression equation estimated was log X -l4.309 + 1.435 log X + 4.052 log x + 1 (3.174) (2.843) 2 (3.681) 3 .003 X4 - .050 X5 (.959) (-4.476) R2 = .90 D. w. = 1.00 where: X1 = constant dollar value of Brazil's manufactured exports; X2 = dollar inflation adjusted real effective exchange rate (Cr$/US$1.00); 82 X II fiscal incentives for eXport; >< ll 4 total world imports; and proxy for capacity utilization (residuals from time regression line of Brazilian industrial production). X m II The t values appear in parentheses beneath the regression coefficients. The estimated Durbin-Watson statistic indicates a problem of significant autocorrelation of residuals. Whereas the independent variables X2, X3, and X5 all are statistically significant at the 1 percent level, X4 is significant at only about the 30 percent level. All variables show the expected signs. In this regression study, the real effective exchange rate, X2, shows a relatively high elasticity of 1.4, which indicated the importance of relative prices in affecting the supply of exports. Xs's negative sign and its high level of statistical significance indicate the existence Of a recession-boom effect on capacity utilization and on exports. In periods of domestic recession, such as occurred in 1965, producers try to place their output in foreign markets. The regression coefficient Of .050, however, is rather low. Therefore, this factor is not of overall importance and might diminish with time as the export of manufactures becomes a more regular activity. . The estimated elasticity of the fiscal incentive variable X3 was 4.1, very high, more than double that of the real exchange rate. The interviews conducted by Tyler 83 suggest that this result could be attributed to the indirect or qualitative effect of the fiscal incentives. As a result of the governmental incentives, producers became more and more interested in exporting. With time, this qualitative effect should be smoothed out, and the estimated parameter might fall to a value closer to the elasticity Of the real effective exchange rate. Tyler also has used a similar methodology to analyze the period between 1961 and 1968, and, quite interestingly, the results did not show the importance of the fiscal incentives. Tyler concluded, then, that the fiscal incentives were too recent, that they had affected only a few Observations, and that there was a lag in their effect. That is why, although entrepreneurs had given importance to the fiscal incentives for exports, those incentives failed to be significant in the regres- sion analysis for the earlier period. Doellinger's Regression Analysis of BraziIian Dynamic Experts The model utilized by Tyler to analyze Brazilian exports apparently was developed in collaboration with the IPEA (Instituto de Planejamento Economico e Social) group. This group, headed by Carlos Von Doellinger, ran regres- sion equations similar to Tyler's to explain the behavior of exports of nontraditional primary products and 6See Tyler, "Fiscal Incentives," p. 33, note 10. 84 manufactured products from 1963 to 1968, that is, prior to the minidevaluations.7 Nontraditional primary products included all primary products except coffee, grains, cotton, cocoa, bananas, and carnauba wax. Those "traditional" primary products were excluded because the purpose of the research was to analyze the factors influencing the export expansion Of products which did not have much importance in Brazil's foreign trade previous to the 19605. For both nontradi- tional primary products and for manufactured products (Classes 5,6,7,and 8 of the SITC), Brazil's participation in world trade is marginal. Consequently, the inter- national market price can be considered exogeneous, and the foreign demand for the Brazilian products studied can be assumed to be perfectly elastic during the period under examination. The best statistical results Obtained can be summarized in the supply functions presented below. The first supply function involves exports of nontraditional primary products (quarterly data from 1963 to 1968). log X1 = 7.28 + 0.541 log X2 + 2.12 log X3 - 4.61 D (1.93) (7.15) ' (6.36) F = 30.2 R2 — 0.85 Doellinger, et al., ExportapOes. 85 The coefficients of t and F are significant at 5 percent, and X1 = constant dollar value Of eXports of the various products; X2 = real exchange rate (Cr$ per US$1.00) deflated by the wholesale price Of agricultural products, except coffee); X3 = production index Of the previous period based on exported primary products; and D = dummy variable, which assumes value 1 during the first semester of each year so as to take into account the effects Of the period, between harvests, when external sales are extremely reduced. The function denotes a high elasticity coefficient of production, 2.12, indicating that good harvests help to increase exports, and a rather low elasticity coeffi- cient with respect to the rate of exchange, 0.54. This means that the variations that occurred in the rate of exchange during the period, generally quite large and difficult to predict, have had only a limited influence on foreign sales of nontraditional primary products. The second function involves manufactured products (quarterly data from 1963 to 1968). log x1 = 3.82 + 0.63 log x + 1.48 log x (1.09) 2 (3.39) 3 - 2.31 log X4 -0.74 D (-2.91) (-4.70) R2 = 0.91 D. w. = 1.97 86 The coefficients are significant at 5 percent, except for the exchange rate, which is significant at 10 percent, and X1 = dollar value of exports of manufactured goods; X 2 real exchange rate, deflated by the wholesale price index of industrial products and inflated by the index of remuneration to exporters via fiscal incentives (following Tyler's approach and index); X3 = production index of exportable industrial goods; X4 = index of utilization of industrial capacity (based on index of variation of employment); and D = dummy variable, which assumes value of 1 during 1963 and the first two quarters of 1964, to take into account the institutional changes that occurred after 1964. The results show the very important influence of the index of capacity utilization. The coefficient, with a negative sign, is the highest, reflecting the tendency during this period for exporters of industrial goods to regard foreign sales more as an residual outlet available during domestic recessions rather than as a regular activity. The foreign exchange-fiscal incentive index, X2, has an elasticity coefficient lower than one (0.63) and has little significance. As already noted, this contrasts with results obtained by Tyler, whose study included part of the period during which the minidevalua- tions were in effect. The production index is less rele— vant here than in the case of primary products. 87 The important conclusion of the IPEA study is that during the period 1963-1968, despite existing incentives for exports, the external commercial activities of Brazilian producers depended more on the conditions of supply (for primary products) and domestic demand (for manufactured products) than on the conscious determination of exporters to seek foreign markets. It is only after the institution of the minidevaluations in August 1968, aided by the establishment of tax credits in 1969, that exports of both manufactured goods and primary products started to boom. Tyler's Regression Analysis of Minidevaluations In another regression model Tyler attempted to incorporate the frequency of devaluation as a variable influencing exports of manufactured goods. The result however, was not conclusive. Using quarterly data from 1961 to 1970, he estimated the following regression equation: log X1 = -l3.577 + 1.415 log X2 + .005 X3 (-3.386) (2.628) (.546) + 2.634 X4 + 1.238 X5 - .037 X6 (1.430) (1.405) (-2.184) 2 R = .90 D.W. = .91 where: X1 = constant dollar value of Brazil's manufactured exports; 88 X2 = dollar inflation adjusted real effective exchange rate for manufactured exports (Cr$ per US$1.00); X3 = absolute (that is, without signs) percentage variation in X 2; X4 = fiscal incentives for export; X = total world imports; and X6 = proxy variable for Brazilian industrial capacity utilization (residuals from time trend regression line for industrial production). The results are similar to those presented pre- viously. The independent variables X and X 2 4 5 all are statistically significant, the first two at the and X6’ X 5 percent level, the latter two at the 15 percent level. The exchange rate variable X2 was significant and presented a high elasticity of 1.4, but the frequency of devaluation variable, X3, was not significant and did not show the theoretically "correct" negative sign, although it had a very low regression coefficient of .005. Therefore, this test of the minidevaluation policy proved inconclusive.8 Tyler also combined the real exchange rate and fiscal incentives into the real rate of effective remunera- tion to Brazilian industrial exporters and represented by X7 to estimate the alternative regression equation, with" the use of quarterly data from 1961 to 1970 (see Table III-2): 8Tyler, "Exchange Rate Flexibility," pp. 19-19b. 89 log x = 3.857 + 1.616 log x + .001 x 1 (3.551) (2.775) 7 (.139) 3 + .008 X5 - .035 X6 (6.364) (-3.380) 2 R = .88 D.W. = .90 where variables X7, X5, and X6 are statistically signifi- cant at the 5 percent level. As before, X3, indicating the frequency of devaluations, is insignificant. Effects of Minidevaluations on Exports of Manufactured Products: An Interpretation There is an additional interpretation for Tyler's regression analysis not to show the importance of the fiscal incentives for the period 1961 to 1968 but, rather, to show that they were very important when the data for 1969 and 1970 were added (see pages 81-83 above). Only after the minidevaluations were initiated in August 1968 did firms have a guarantee that the level of remuneration of exports would not fluctuate widely. Therefore, minide- valuations represented a continuity in the level of fiscal incentives, and, to a certain extent, they also represented a guarantee that the remuneration for exports would remain satisfactory during the future period, when medium- and long-run contracts could be agreed upon. Figure III-1 shows the progress of exports of manufactured goods and of total exports, the index of remuneration to eXporters of industrial products through fiscal incentives to export, 5.. vv (L) O '- A}! UY .... 1 !n d“ .‘r bu ‘- ' o .D .n ‘i ' 1 (l! ”v. ‘ . n. - I ~~ A.‘ 90 ~the index of the real effective exchange rate as adjusted to dollar inflation, and the index of the rate of real effective remuneration. The last named index is the combination of the first two indexes. It can be observed that whereas the index of remuneration through fiscal incentives becomes important after the end of 1965 and increases steadily thereafter, the real effective exchange rate as adjusted to dollar inflation fluctuates violently between 1961 and 1964, rather widely between 1964 and 1967, and only moderately from 1968 onward. The combination of these two indexes, the rate of real effective remuneration, shows upward and downward movements until August 1968, when it shows an almost steady movement upward from then on. The effect of this trend on exports is apparent. Exports of manufactured goods which had increased from US$204 millions in 1962 to US$381 millions in 1968, according to the broad CACEX definition, already a reasonably good performance, experienced exceptional growth rates from 1968 onward, as shown in Table III-3. The compounded growth rate for the period 1969-1972 was approximately 31 percent (CACEX broad definition). The level of about US$1.1 billion dollars (CACEX broad defini- tion) was reached in 1972, approximately the same as the y/zi.lue of coffee exports. Although the world trade share of Brazilian manufactures in these products is still I’l'egligible (0.1 percent in 1969), the annual increase in k 91 Figure III-1.--The Effects of Devaluations of the Exchange Rate and of Fiscal Incentives on Brazilian Exports, 1960-1972. 993 iafl 5 million" ‘ I'vkl 4000—} 3800—1 U 5 ° . . J milli'wn. PIN 3600'“ .360 3400'“ »J4Cr Period of mini-devel t ns 3200-4 .323 Index 3000 - {300 r30!)- 2800 “ >280 NW» 2600‘“ L260 ~,w Rate of Real Effective Remuneration to Industri 2400a Exporters r1 >240 *240 ." .\ ; ’ \'\ I. _ I ‘ \ .r' 2200 [I [1 l‘ 0! : >22( bzy) ’ ‘ f\\ I I I 5‘8.; . ‘ \ I :N.. I \II V ‘ H 7 \ 2000 ... 201 v | .' \\,'l t/\ ~200 r282»: (1961) § ; f ‘\ Real Exchange Rate i : /// leoo -* Adjusted to Dollar ' 4 : , >189 ”180' Inflation | I] l l I 1600 .. (Using wholesale price index for :11 commoditi both in Brazil and in the U.S.A.) 1‘00 -( U.S. $10269 1200 '4 millions (1960) 92 0.5. S 3990 millions (1972) r”’ LI I ‘J r’ U.S. $1,226 millions (1964) (1960) \ Index of Remuneration to Exporters of Industrial Products Via the BOO -( Fiscal Incentives to Export 60¢) )—~ 400 --- 200 — 0.5. $204 llions (1964) -- v“’..- --4 OJ $21;:-93.1.1.i.222-9.9_63>_--..——-r" ' 149. 61 P—f—f—I- (1971’ ”1‘0 ”143 I <:\\\ // Exports of Basic » ~16® V, Products 160 P120 '14: [100 L109 '80-? Exports of Manufactured Goods Accord~ ing to ”Broad"*5U” Definition (New CACEX clas- sification). Exports of manufac- llturers (excluding ’1’ semi-manufacturess) 1 according to new CACEX .200 ,--°‘ classification. :Exporti of manufacturers accordin| to old classification. _40'? I I ’é;‘f§8fil5khi§ikli&blbiiilfllefiilé (.961 I982 iiil’llld (I 535’ 6dikl {7F} ISO} lm I“! I8” I“? I866 3808 IO'IO 187! (972 9Z3 o.mm v.m~ «maa v.5m o.ommm tha II I- o.mm m.m~ «mm 0.8 o.vom~ Head mm.oo «.ma o.oom m.vm m.vm mow o.mm NHHH mumom muma mnwmhm onma m.m¢ h.m m.vmm m.m~ v.Hm mmv m.nm m.h w.am~ m.m~ N.~Hmm mmma n.@ I a.m H.mma H.HH m.o~ Hmm m.m I m.@ o.oma h.mH m.HmmH mmma hm.am o.oa m.mma H.5H n.0m mvm v.5v m.m h.mva o.H I o.vmma swam o.m H.h m.v~a ~.m m.ma mam H.maI m m m mm m.v v.thH wmma o.mm m.h n.0ma ~.mm m.ha vmm w.mm m.w mnmoa o.HH m.mmma mmma «.mm m.m ¢.ow II m.vHI vow m.ww o.v a mu m.a m.m~va vmma H.NH o.m n.Hv II II II o.ma n.~ v.5m m ma m wova mood m.QAI H.m N.nm II II II m.oaI >.N H.mm m.maI ~.vama Nwma m.mv o.m n.mv II II II ¢.~w n.~ m.mm o.oa o.mova Head o.mm m.m o.mm II II II m.mn n.a n.mm H.H I m.mmma coma n.m v.H H.ma II II II H.m o.a «.ma H.m o.mm~a mmma m.oaI m.a m.ma II II II o.v I o.a N.NH m.aHI o.mvma mmma II m.a N.ma II II II H.m I m.o n.~a m.m I w.amma nmma II II II II II II m.mHI m.o H.ma a.v o.~mva mmma II II II II II II n.ao n.a m.ma n.m I m.mmva mmma II h.o N.HH II II II m.m v.0 v.m m.a m.meH vmma II II II II II II II w.o m.m II m.mmma mmma Awe Ame mms no Awe lav am: no Ame lav mma mo Ame mm: no name mwuom muuomxm mcoHHHHE mmumm muuoaxm mcoflaaflz mmumm muuomxm mcoHHHaz mmumm mcofiaaaz zu30nu Hmuoe :u3ouu Hmuoe nuzouo Hmuoa nu3ouo Hmsccd Aconc¢ amsccd Hooded mIm mommmHU UBHm cofluHCAqu pw0um COAuficmeo 3onumz Amomv Amomv Axmooz\xmoxxx .moasocoom musucsflcoo “wwnma mono "mwawmmumv Han Hmscd ofluoumamm .Hflmmum on Hmuucmo oocmm «Amuse» Hmum>mm wwHow 302w moflummumum mmmuh HmcoHumcumucH mo xoommmm» .mcofiuwz pmufica no magma "Amnmav N .02 .moa .moHEOcoom pauo3 wo 3mfl>mm .>H£ou< mmcoflaummromuuw3ufioz =.mmmu cmflaflnoum one "mmwuucsou pmnwamfluumSUQHIwEmm mo >mmumuum quEmon>mo mm manomxm pwusuommscmz mo :oHuOEoum: .mmmom uSEHmm “Hammum 0p oocmm .xmoDZ\xMUaumcumuaa .AMIHHH manna aw COeuwcmep zouumcv mwma Hausa moflumeumum cmflaflumum Ansoflmwo cfi pom: .m .5 .w .m mommmHU um w>wumcuwuad .Amomav oceozs can lawmauwmmav qflumcumua< “AZmzv mmaqumuumz op muflwaammum mudumHocmEoz mnu co pmmmm an .imwma .xuo» 302V some Nm>usm muecoseoo cfl QdBUZD xn .mHmmem u0w .pmmb .nmamumfi couflcocv mm Emu“ unocuflz m .n .w .m mommmHU "m m>HumcumuH¢ .m .Hnasm\ma\oe .006 caeoz: an .0Ha58x0 qu .powo ma coauacawmp were .vIo mommmao mo muospoua umzuo meow paw .m .h .m .m mommmau "m w>flumcuwua< .COHUHCHMQU mflflu CO muwmwfl mum mUHumflumuw H.840 0S8 om .NI .0 am mmmmeU "H 0>HUMCHQHH< "roeHms aceumoeoammmao 06609 HmcoaumcumucH vumecmum co cwmmm 16 .mucwESUOp pcm moflumaumum mpmuu an manmaam>m one muospoumlowusuumMscme wo mcofluflcflwwp Hmum>om 1’82 1‘ -" ”fit: Is 1": .1 (I; O (I. D I. ‘ '0 q: ‘I I . s 95 world trade was only 15.2 percent (SITC classes 5 to 8) as compared to over 50 percent (SITC classes 5 to 8) for Brazil's exports during 1969-1970. The spreading diversification of exports with regard to products and countries also has been an important achievement of the last decade. The share of manufactures in Brazil's total exports grew from 1 percent in 1958 to 11- 2 percent (narrow definition) in 1970, or from 14.3 percent in 1964 to 28.4 percent (CACEX broad definition) in 1972. That industry has become more and more export minded is evidenced in Brazil's exports of manufactures. The growth rate in this section has been about three times higher than the industrial production of the country, which had a compounded growth rate of 12.1 from 1968 to 1971 - The participation of exports of manufactures in the industrial product, although low, increased from about 3 percent in 1967-1969 to an estimated 5 percent in 1970 (narrow definition) . 9 All kinds of manufactured products are being exPorted by Brazil, including shoes and refrigerators to the Uni ted States, clocks to Switzerland, clothes to Italy, testing and measuring instruments to Germany, photoelectric cells to the Netherlands, and cars, buses, See Carlos von Doellinger, "Exportacdes brasil- eiras: diagnéstico e perspectivas," Pesquisa e Planejamento, 1 (June 1971), 83—140. 96 electronic products, and office machines to other Latin 0 O 10 0 I O O I O U ZUnerican countries. ThlS impre351ve diver31f1cation of Brazil's manufactured exports is illustrated in Table III-4, which shows the exports of semiprocessed and manufactured goods during 1971. The participation of the most important single items in the total value of exports was relatively low: 1.71 percent for soluble coffee and 1.75 percent for processed beef among the manufactured goods; 2.47 percent for sawn pinewood and 1.35 percent for castor oil among the semiprocessed goods.ll LAFTA countries, as shown in Table III-5, continue to be the most important buyers of Brazil's manufactures, as they were in the early 1960s. This is to be expected in view of their proximity and of the advancement of Brazil's industry in relation to that of those countries. Brazil may be in a good position to supply equipment which suits the conditions of countries at similar or less advanced stages of development. DeSpite the fact that exports of manufactured products to LAFTA countries has increased substantially, their share in Brazil's exports diminished from 52 percent in 1965 to 35 percent in 1970 10See Hesse, "Promotion of Manufactured Exports," pp. 252-54. 11It is interesting to note in Table III-4 that although the participation of industrialized goods in total dollar. value of exports in 1971 was 28.3 percent, their Paytlclpation in total weight (tons) was only 6.95 percent. This only confirms the generally known fact that the density value of industrialized goods is much greater than that Of raw materials. 97 {TABLE III-4.--Brazi1's Total Exports and Exports of Industrial Goods in 1971 (CACEX Broad Classification). Participation in 1971 Total Exports (%) US$ US$ Millions 1,000 Millions 1,000 FOB Tons FOB Tons Total exports of 2903.6 43824.5 100 100 all products (A+B+C+D+E) A: Industrial 822.0 3043.3 28.31 6.95 ggc>ods a1) semipro- 239.3 1271.4 8.24 2.90 c_:_essed goods l-carnauba wax 10.6 12.7 0.37 0.03 2-iron and steel 8.7 89.0 0.30 0.20 for rerolling 3-pig iron 5.9 112.9 0.20 0.26 4-iron alloys 6.8 19.6 0.24 0.04 5-pinewood, sawn 71.8 583.0 2.47 1.33 6-sawn wood, other 10.2 117.2 0.36 0.27 than pine '7-cocoa butter 24.3 21.1 0.83 0.05 8-pea11ut oil, raw 22.9 62.0 0.79 0.14 9-castor oil, raw 39.3 132.7 1.35 0.30 lO-Ofcher vegetable 1.6 7.4 0.06 0.02 9118 (excluded items 8-9), raw ll-wood pulp 4.6 33.3 0.16 0.08 lZ-hides and skins, 14.0 5.6 0.48 0.01 Prepared or tanned TABLE III-4 . --Continued. ’— 98 Participation in 1971 Total Exports (%) US$ US$ Millions 1,000 Millions 1,000 FOB Tons FOB Tons B—semiproces—n .4 .4 0.00 0.00 sed steel mill Iproducts (ex- czluded items 2-3-4) 314——c>ther semi- 18.3 79.4 0.63 0.17 §>rocessed pro- diucts k>) manufac- 582.8 1771.8 20.07 4.05 tured lS-rubber, pro- 4.7 4.2 0.16 0.01 cessed 16-ccoffee, 49.7 23.3 1.71 0.05 processed l7-footwear 29.3 7.1 1.01 0.02 l8—boilers, 38.4 19.9 1.32 0.04 machines, and mechanical ap- paratuses and instruments (excluded items 24-25-26) l9-beef, processed 50.9 34.3 1.75 0.08 20-iron, steel, or 9.9 68.5 0.34 0.16 steel alloy plates, hot- rolled or cold- rolJLead 21-cotton yarn 6.8 6.5 0.24 0.01 22"W00d veneers 18.6 32.7 0.64 0.07 99 TABLE III-4.--Continued. Participation in 1971 Total Exports (%) US$ Millions 1,000 Millions 1,000 FOB Tons Tons 23-e1ectrical 28.5 6.4 0.98 0.02 machines, ap- paratuseSIand other electrical appliances for technical use 24-office machines 27.1 2.3 0.93 0.01 and accessories 25-earthamoving, 5.9 3.1 0.20 0.01 digging,and drilling equip- ment 26-machine tools, 4.6 2.9 0.16 0.01 parts and acces- sories 27—rolling stock 25.0 13.2 0.86 0.03 -and vehicles 28-other steel-mill 19.6 119.6 0.68 0.27 products (ex- cluded item 20) 29-molasses, edible 8.6 454.3 0.30 1.04 30-menthol 17.1 1.6 0.60 0.00 31-essentia1 oils 10.4 4.9 0.4 0.01 32-vegetable and 36.9 79.1 1.27 0.18 fruit juices 33-cotton fabrics 11.0 8.9 0.38 0.02 34-glass and glass- 14.2 22.3 0.48 0.05 were 35-other manufac- 165.6 856.8 5.70 1.96 tured goods 100 TABLE III-4.--Continued. Participation in 1971 Total Exports (%) US$ US$ Millions 1,000 Millions 1,000 FOB Tons FOB Tons B: Basic prod- 1987.9 40342.2 68.46 92.05 ucts, raw materials” C: Ship-chand- 22.2 217.7 0.77 0.50 1er's supplies D: Re-exports 6.1 184.1 0.21 0.42 E: Special Trans- 65.3 37.6 2.25 0.08 actions Source: CACEX/NUCEX, Banco do Brasil. The classification of manufactured and semiprocessed goods is a combination of the criteria adopted by INTAL (1966-1967) and UNCTAD (1965). (narrow definition). The U.S. percentage share of Brazil's manufactured products reached a peak of 36 percent in 1968 and then declined to 21 percent in 1970, whereas the share of EEC and several other countries increased.12 Effects on Exports of Non- Manufactured Products The effects of the minidevaluations also were apparent on exports of products other than manufactured 12The data of this paragraph and of Table III-5 are based on the classification of manufactures used by CACEX during 1971 and published in the Boletim (Banco do Brasil), 6 (1971). In 1972, CACEX started to use another one, the broader classification of Table III-4. 101 .xm0cu «Aacaav N .02 .o .Hflmmum oo oocmm Ewuoaom "condom m~.o mm~.a nm.o Hen na.o nvm ma.o hem so.o moa oa. oma macmmoo H~.v mmo.ma mm.o mmm.~ mm.o mHH.H «v.0 mum Hm.o awn mm.a mom.a mowuud mv.~ mam.aa nm.a Hnm.m mm.a moo.v mv.~ oma.m mm.~ Hmm.m wa.m nov.m mmwuucsoo cwem< nocuo mm.~ Hmv.aa HN.H mnv.m mm.H Nam.~ ~m.v vm~.oa ha.o omm hm.H mma.~ smash vm.a mom.m no.0 omn.a vm.o mam mm.o one ww.o mmo.a am. mmv mowuucsoo cmmmousm Honuo mm.a Hem.> mm.o vmm.a vo.o mmm.a mv.~ mma.m ow.o amm mm. mm~.H mmousm cuoumom ~w.o mmm.mm oa.m vnm.na vm.m NMH.~H av.v mmm.m mo.m mmh.h vm.m vom.m d a m m ~v.o~ mom.~m om.ma mmm.mm mv.va oom.mm no.ma mmm.mm mm.NH vom.mH ma.va mne.- U m m om.a mmm.m wo.a mvo.m ma.a mam.m mm.a mmm.m mm.H mvo.m mH.H Hom.H mmfiuucdoo cmofluoE< umnuo om.vm mcm.mma wm.mm mav.oaa va.mm www.m5 Nn.mm va.oh mm.mm vmm.aw wm.~m Hum.am «Hmdq mc.m mmm.~a Ho.m ann.m mm.m mwn.v MH.H mwm.~ vv.~ hoh.m nm.o mmm.a mpmcwu on.o~ Hmm.mm 55.nm omm.mn hm.vm Hmm.an mo.mm www.ma mm.vm mHN.mm v>.- www.mm 4 m D oo.ooa www.mmv 00.00H mom.hmm oo.ooa Hmo.vom oo.ooa vo~.mo~ oo.ooa o~H.va oo.oo~ omm.mma deuce a mm: m mmD a me a mmD a mm: w me Gmemm osma mmma mmma nmma woma mmma .Amom ooo.ammsv oemaumwma mumxumz ucmuwuueo 0» mmusuumozcmz no muuomxm m.He~mumII.mIHHH mqm.w m.ma ¢.v~ o.HH cmnoum Ho omaawco .mmwm >.Hm h.nh m.moa H.mv m.mm n.om n.5m m.vm moooo H.nma v.vma o.mma m.oma m.om o.HHH h.mm m.moa HooaIcouuoo o.wva m.mma o.mHH m.aoa v.om m.ow o.mm o.mm Homom m.em~ m.mom v.5va m.moa m.moa m.ooH o.moa 0.0m who couH m.mhh m.mmm o.mam m.vhh >.von o.vmh m.wo> h.mmb mommoo cmmno o.mmmm o.mmom o.vnom o.mHmH o.oomH o.HHma o.mvva o.aama o.oNNH manomxm venom Hmuoa whoa Head chma mwma mmma bmma mmma mmmH emaa .Aooo.ooo.amma momv HHumHm mo mpuomxm oammm ucmuuomEH umoz mo mmSHm> uuomeII.hIHHH mamda .Hflmmum op oocmm .meDZ\me¢o .Hhma momma :mwmuom .memum ”condom 106 th H.mom w.HmH w.HmH w.HMH h.mHH w.HNH w.HHH .OOH muuomxm HMHOB m.m¢m o.va w.bhH 5.5NH m.HNH N.hva 5.0ma OOH manomxo owmun Hmnao b.wahm m.mmvH,o.omh 0.0mm o.ovm h.mm¢ h.wmm 00H noun HO mxoo cmwnwom o.oomm m.mhhm m.vmaa m.mmma w.mmh m.NmHH o.~wm OOH CHOU cmnoum m.omm o.oow w.mmm H.vhH m.hm ~.HHH n.0HN 00H HO cmaawno .mmmm m.hhH m.m- o.mom m.NMH H.ObH h.mvH w.ah OOH mOOOU m.wNH w.N¢H o.HmH m.o~H m.mm m.~oa v.mm OOH HOO3IGOHHOU N.v¢¢ m.mmm m.m¢m m.hom w.m¢~ m.mv~ h.mmH OOH Hmmnm v.¢m~ o.omN m.NmH m.OMH m.hNH m.¢NH n.5NH COH who GOHH h.HOH m.MNH c.50H m.HOH w.Nm m.ooa o.mm OOH mmuuoo cmmuu mmm «.mma «.moa H.m¢H m.mNH m.ooa H.mHH m.moH cod muuomxm meom dance «pad Head Chad mead coma head mead mead vomd ..eea I mead 060» «meme uuuomxm ownmm smeafiuoum mo nonwocH QOGflEHOHHOmll.m|HHH Mandfi 107 only exception was coffee, but this was due to the 1969 frost. In 1972 coffee exports performed almost as well as in the high years of 1969 and 1970. Wide price fluctuations, however, due to weather conditions and other factors, always have characterized primary products trade. Table III-9 illustrates those wide fluctuations in the price indexes of some Brazilian basic export goods in the period of 1964-1971. Cocoa, in particular, has shown the most violent variations in prices from year to year. To diminish the risk facing any country which depends on a limited number of commodities subject to great price fluctuations, Brazil has been moving in the right direction by diversifying its exports. This is most dramatically illustrated by the case of coffee. During the 1950s, coffee's contribution to Brazil's total exports amounted to an annual average of 62 percent. This share decreased to 27 percent in 1971. Table III-10 shows the export share of major basic export goods during 1964-1971. Iron ore, sugar, beef, corn, and soybeans are some of the primary products which have substantially widened their share of total Brazilian exports in recent years. Concluding Overall Evidence Concerning Total Exports It was shown that exports of both industrialized and basic products have improved substantially since August 1968, during which time the policy of minidevaluations was in effect. In summarizing this evidence, three types of 108 TABLE III- 9. --Price Indexes of Some Basic Export Goods Dollar Price (Base period: 1965-1967= 100) 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 Green 110 113 98.1 91.1 90.7 93.3 127 coffee Sugar 166 94.8 102 102 126 132 142 Cotton 104 102 98.2 100 110 93.1 93.9 Cocoa 108 69.8 105 120 141 204 150 123 Iron ore 108 106 101 94.0 90.6 89.7 97.5 Source: Conjuntura Econémica, 27 (March 1973), 130. results regarding total Brazilian exports will be described below. First, Figure III-2 gives moving quarterly averages of the (monthly) dollar value of total Brazilian exports from 1964 to 1972. Two linear functions relating total (exports and time are adjusted to the series of data for the period previous to the minidevaluation policy (from January 1964 to August 1968) and for the period of the minidevaluation policy (from August 1968 to 1972). Whereas the slope of the first function denotes moderate improve- ment in exports in the first period, the slope of the second function clearly indicates the exceptional rate of growth in exports that occurred in the second period. Second, the substantial increase in diversification attained by Brazilian exports in recent years is illustrated 109 Figure III-2.--Total Brazilian Exports, Quarterly Moving Averages, US$ millions FOB, 1964-1972. Note: The regressions were calculated with approximate monthly data taken from a figure published in ExPortacao 1947-1972, CACEX, Banco do Brasil. 110 Nb an on me vwma one» we sawuocsu es uuuomxo Heuou "meme HesaeIaemH .uaou ocoaunsao>opecaa uo poguom and now sodassvo usOCAH covenant yam.~ + omH I x van.o + NHH u x mad» mo c0wuucsu no muuoaxm Hmuoe "mead .mstIvoaa .cmn .oofluom COwueDHm>ooacwanum on» new refinance undead covenant ..e~ Io. ..oe ..ee Iced IONA Io.” I e: Iced I eea I 02 I o: I SN I O: I 8... 1.o~n NSOdHHfiI » .m.a 111 .Hflmmum 0p oocmm .xm032\xm0¢0 .Han mocha ammonom .Hflmmum "mousom OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH manomxm Hmuoe m.OH O.mH 0.0H OO.mH N.OH N.OH O.HH «.mH monomxm 0Hmmn umcuo O.~ O.H O.H O.H 0.0 0.0 e.O ~.O spun no 0x80 sponsom O.~ O.~ O.H O.m O.H O.H O.H m.O choc e.m m.~ O.H H.H v.O e.O O.H 0.0 cmuonm no pmHHHco .mmmm H.m m.~ O.e m.~ m.e H.e m.~ m.m moooo e.e O.m 0.0 0.0 O.e m.O 0.0 m.a couuoo O.m O.e O.m e.m m.e O.e m.m m.~ spasm H.O O.e m.O O.m m.m O.m 0.0 O.m 0H0 couH 0.0N O.mm 0.0m O.HO 0.0m O.me m.ee H.mm weapon cameo O.HO e.me 0.0e e.Oe m.OO «.mm ~.~O O.mm manomxm onmm Hmuoe HOOH OOOH OOOH OOOH OOOH OOOH mOmH eOOH .HOOHIOOOH monomxm cmHHHNmum Hmuoe cH mcooo uuomxm owmmm “ohm: mo wumchI.oHIHHH names 112 in Tables III-11 and III-12. These tables classify all export goods according to ten different sectors. Table III-ll shows that, in terms of index numbers, all ten sectors showed remarkable growth from 1968 to 1971, in general much greater than that obtained from 1964 to 1968. As some of the sectors, such as animal products, products of chemical and allied industries, mineral products, manu- factures of base metals, electrical machinery and appli- ances, and "other products" presented very high rates of growth, their percentage share in total exports rose to more prominent positions. As a result, the export compo- sition in 1971 already was substantially modified with respect to that of 1968. Vegetable products, in particular, in spite of a 20 percent increase in exports in those four years, had their participation in total exports reduced from 68 percent in 1968 to 53 percent in 1971. Third, Table III-13 gives evidence of the increas- ing market diversification obtained by Brazilian exports. In particular, the concentration of goods sent to the U.S. market has diminished substantially. The U.S. share of total Brazilian exports dropped from an average of 33 percent during 1964-1968 to 26 percent in 1969-1971. This is a continuation of a postwar trend which has accompanied the movement away from dependence on coffee. The average U.S. share of Brazilian exports during the 19503 was 46 percent when coffee's share in total exports was 57 percent. 113 u.omm «.mmm O.vOm v.OO~ v.mm~ O.mMH >.Omm OOH meumE omen mo moHoHuum pom mHmumE ommm .n m.mm~ m.mmm m.mnH O.va m.mmH m.mmH m.va OOH mposooum Hmuocwz .O v.5me 0.0om m.HON m.va 0.0om O.mnH m.hHH OOH mmwuu Insch cmHHHm com HMOHEono mo moosoonm .m m.>mH 0.0NH m.va v.HOH O.mn m.mm O.mm OOH moHoHpum mHHuxmu pom mHHuxmB .v 0.00N m.OOH O.HOH m.va m.mm O.mm H.OHH OOH mmxm3 ocm mumm .meo oHnm»omm> can HmEHcd .m m.mmH m.mOH v.5vH H.OmH e.mHH m.mNH 0.00H OOH muosooum 0Hn800m0> .m monsoonm N.Hmo H.vmv m.mmm O.MHN v.va «.mOH 0.00N OOH HmEHcm pom mHmEHcm 0>HH .H Ohm H.mom O.HOH O.HOH O.HmH n.mHH O.HNH O.HHH OOH Hmuoe NOOH HOOH OOOH mmmH mmmH OOOH OOOH mmmH «OOH muouoom .OOHuvmmH "066m pumpesz xmchO OeOHIeOOH .mpouomm mp mesoexm amHHaNmumII.HHIHHH mamas .HHmmum op ooomm .xmooz\xmo¢o .HeOH moons omHouom.oHHmoum “mouoom 114 m.mmm O.hom O.mmH h.vHH 5.5HH m.¢m 0.0m OOH muODQOHm Honuo .OH m.emm e.OOH O.HO N.Nm H.8NH 0.00 O.OO OOH ooosoHooo uuoo Imamuu OQHMHoommm chuHoo can mHommo> .moouoau muumm was .ummuo IHHM .moHoHno> .m 0.000 N.Omn O.mmv N.v¢m H.mHm 0.00~ m.mmH OOH moouonu muumm .ucmEmHsvo HMUHHuomHm .moocmemmm HMOHcmnooE can. 06586.: .O 115 mm.m O0.0H mm.H mm.h OO.m HO.mm om.m OH.v NN.OH O0.0 hv.m O>.N H0.00 No.0 vm.~ Om.m HO.H OO.HH HO.m mm.mm ON.O mm.H Hm.m mO.m om.mm mm.v OH.m mm.h OO.H mm.m mm.m mm.mm mm.m mm.H OH.m mm.O mm.OH Ov.N hv.mm OH.v hm.m mm.m O0.0 Ob.m MH.m mH.OO mo.m v~.H mHmuoE ommn mo moHoHpHm pom mHmuoE ommm nv.n muospoum HmuocHS O0.0 mmHho ImsooH poHHHm cam HmowEono mo muosponm MN..NH mGHUHuLHN @HHHXQH pom oHHoxos OO.m mmxmz pom mumm .mHHo mHQmuomo> pom HMEHcd monsooum oHnmuomm> OH.OO mm.m muosposm HmEHcm pom meEHcm o>HH NOOH HOmH muuomxm Hmuoe SH mumcm ommucooumm .wuouoom >9 OOOH mmmH OOOH bmmH OOOH mOOH vmmH wuouoom .HhmHIOOmH monomxm GMHHHNMHmII.NHIHHH MHmdB .HHmmum 0o oocmm .xMUDZ\xMU .moouocp human can .uwmuo IHHM .anOHnm> .m Hw.m OO.m Hm.m mm.H mO.N NO.H mm.H O0.0 newsman manna .usmfimHovo HMOHHuomHo .moOGMHHmmm HMUHcmcooE poo HuooHoonz .O .HHmmum ow oocmm .xmoDzIme¢U .Han coomua cmHoHom .HHmmum “monsom 117 N.O H.O H.O H.O H.O H.O N.O N.O OHCMOOO o.m N.m H.H O.N O.H O.H m.H O.H MOHHM4 ¢.m m.m v.m H.N O.H N.m O.H N.N mmwuunsoo cmHmd Hocuo m.m m.m m.v H.m v.m v.~ O.H O.H compo O.m O.v m.m H.m H.N H.N m.N m.¢ mOHHu¢5OU commouflm snoumoz Hocuo 4.6 H.O m.o H.e O.e H.e e.o ~.O ooouom ououmom H.OH O.~H «.mH O.HH m.~H H.OH H.OH O.NH a a m m m.e~ H.ON O.O~ m.m~ m.e~ e.e~ O.m~ O.e~ o m m e.O e.O m.O ~.O m.O m.O H.O H.O mmHuooooo cmoHHoE4 Hozuo N.NH H.HH O.HH m.OH O.O O.OH HO.NH e.O camaq O.H O.H O.H O.H O.H O.H O.H O.H monomo H.ON a.e~ e.o~ m.mm H.Om e.mm O.~m «.mm a m a HeOH OOOH OOOH OOOH OOOH OOOH mOOH OOOH moonom .HOOHIvOOH 6conom comm mo coHumm IHoHuHmm ommucoonom .chHmom UHEocoom ucoHoHMHo o» muuomxm cmHHHumumII.MHIHHH MHmcfi 118 The movement away from coffee dependence accelerated after 1968, along with concomitant market diversification. The European Economic Community, "other European countries" (aside from the EEC and EFTA), and Japan and other Asian countries have gained most in their shares of Brazilian exports in the past four years. The share of the Latin American Free Trade Association increased moderately, from a 10.6 percent average in 1964-1968 to an 11.4 percent average in 1969-1971. In the whole group of Third World countries, however, a substantial increase is shown, from an average share of 14.7 percent during 1964-1968 to 17.3 percent during 1969-1971. CHAPTER IV ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON INDUSTRIAL EXPORTS As analyzed in Chapter III, there are indications that Brazilian exports have been positively affected by the policy of frequent small adjustments in the exchange rate. Theoretically, the main reason for this beneficial influence is the substantial decrease in risk which characterized exporter remuneration under the previous system of wide fluctuations in the exchange rate. The use of econometric methods to prove this theory has not been successful to date. Tyler's attempts were inconclusive (page 88 above). The major concern of this chapter is to perform a better test of the effects of minidevaluations on the eXport of manufactured products. The first section of this chapter discusses a method for testing the effect of minidevaluations. The second section presents the regression analysis of exports of manufactures. 119 120 The Method for Testing the Effects of Minidevaluations A method for testing the equality of two regression equations--one for the pre-minidevaluation period and another for the minidevaluation period-~13 applied several times in this dissertation. It is explained here by using 0 O l 0 O I Jan Kmenta's exp031tion. Con51der a regre551on equation, + --- + Bk Xik + 8i] which has been estimated for a sample of n observations. Suppose now that m (>K) additional observations are obtained and that one wishes to test the hypothesis that the addi- tional observations come from the same population as the first n observations. For example, suppose that the first n observations are from the period.oowide and unexpected fluctuations in the exchange rate and that the m additional observations come from the period during which the minidevaluations were in effect. If it is expected that the parameters of, say, the export supply function during the minidevaluation period may be dif- ferent from those of the pre-minidevaluation period, the null hypothesis that the parameters of the export supply function have not changed may be tested. To exemplify: lJan Kmenta, Elements of Econometrics (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1971), pp. 373-4. 1 = 81 + 82 X12 + 81 X13t + "’ + Bk xlk + 51 (i = 1,2, ---, n), and Yi = A1 + A2 Xi2 + A3 Xi3 + —-- + 1k Xik + 8i (i = n + 1, n + 2, ---, n + m). The null hypothesis, then, is HO: = Bl = 81’ 82 = 12, ---, Bk = Ak . This is to be tested against the hypothesis that The relevant test statistic is obtained H0 is not true. by applying the leastrsquares estimation method to the first to the second set of data set of data (1 = 1,2, ---, n), n + l, n + 2, ---, n + m), and to the two sets of For the combined = 1! 2! ---l (i= data combined (i set of data, the regression equation is: n + m). Y = --- 51 +62 Xi2 + 53 Xi3 + + 5k Xik + 6i 2: ---I n + m) The sum of squares of the least-squares residuals then can be denoted as: 122 m A A A 2 i=1 n+m Y 2 SSEZ = E ( i - X1 - X2 xi2 - X3 xi3 - --- - Xk Xik) I i=n+1 n+m A A A 2 SSEc = 21 (Y1 - 61 - 62 Xi2 - 83 Xie - --- - 6k Xik) ' 1: where the circumflexes over the coefficients indicate that these are the estimated ones. The appropriate statistic to test Ho is then - + (SSEc 558 5582) /K 1 (SSE1 + SSE2)/(n + m - 2k) ~ Pk, n + m - 2k. This test statistic is applicab1e_only if the number of additional observations exceeds the number of parameters to be estimated, that is, if m > k. If m < k, G. C. Chow and, alternatively, F. M. Fisher, have shown that the appropriate test is as follows.2 To the first n observations fit the least-squares regression Y1 = 81 + 82 X12 + 83 X13 + "’ + Bk xik + 51 2G. C. Chow, "Tests of Equality Between Sets of Coefficients in Two Linear Regressions," Econometrica, Vol. 28, pp. 591-605, 1960; and F. M. Fisher, 1'-Tests of Equality Between Sets of Coefficients in Two Linear Regressions: An Expository Note," Econometrica, Vol. 38, pp. 361-6, 1970. See J. Johnston, Econometric Methods, 2nd Ed. (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 19727, p. 207. 123 and compute the sum of squares of least-squares residuals SSEl. Then, to the pool of n + m sample observations fit the least-squares regression Y.=0+0X.+5X.+---+0 1 1 2 12 3 13 X' + E" k 1k 1 again computing the sum of the squares of residuals SSEC. The test of the null hypothesis that the m additional observations obey the same relation as the first is given by (sss - SSE )/m c 1 ~ F (SSElZTn - k) m,n - k ° The formulation of the hypothesis leading to these F statistics allows for all of the regression parameters to change from one set of data to another. To test an hypothesis involving only some of the regression coeffi- cients requires use of binary or dummy variables. Regression Analysis of Exports of Manufactures Inasmuch as Brazilian exports of industrial goods constitute a very small percentage of total world trade in this category, the world demand encountered by Brazilian industrial exporters may be considered as perfectly elastic. This facilitates the task of estimating an export supply function for these goods. 124 In Tyler's formulation,3 the constant-dollar value of exports of industrial goods is positively related to both the level of real remuneration to exporters and to the level of world trade (proxy for world income) and negatively related to the level of capacity utilization of Brazil's industry. The index of real remuneration to exporters of manufactures is the product of two components: the index of the real exchange rate adjusted to dollar inflation and the index which denotes the level of fiscal incentives for exports of manufactures. Tyler preferred to use these two latter indexesas two separate independent variables instead of simply their product. There is an argument, however, for using the index of real remuneration to exporters. This should be the most relevant variable in affecting the decision of exporters. As the product of the other two, it is clear that a drop in one of the variables may be compensated by a rise in the other. The individual effect of either one of the two depends sub- stantially on the behavior of the other. There is one difficulty in interpreting the influ- ence of industrial capacity utilization on exports of industrial goods. During 1961-1968, when Brazil was passing through great fluctuations in economic activity and exports of industrial goods were in their first and uncertain stage of development, a clear negative relation obtained between intensive use of industrial capacity-~as 3See page 89 above. 125 a sign of a high level of domestic demand--and exports of manufactures. After 1968 the Brazilian economy entered a period of high economic activity and growth which was partly due to the expansion in exports. Thus, this expansion contributed significantly to the greater, if not full, utilization of industrial capacity. There- fore, the negative sign between the proxy for capacity utilization and exports found by Doellinger and Tyler might be reversed when the years 1968-1972 constitute a substantial portion of the period under study.4 Moreover, if this is the case, the index of capacity utilization _should lose its significance as an independent explanatory variable in the export supply function. As a point of departure based on the above rationale, variants of two competing models of the Brazilian industrial export supply function will be tested with the use of quarterly data from 1964 to 1972: log Xlt - 81 + 82 log X2t + 83 log X3t + 84 log X4t + 85 X5t + at; (I) log X1t = 81 + 82 log X6t + 84 log X4t + 85 X5t + 8t (II) This interpretation is supported by the following: the simple correlation coefficient between log xlt and X5t 18 negative, equal to -.53, for the period 1964-1968, and positive, equal to .79, for the period 1968-1972, a dramatic change (See Table IV-l). For Doellinger's and Tyler's results see pages 81 and 85 above. 126 Variants of these models will allow for the deletion of variables which might show insignificance, particularly in the case of X5t' and for different forms of lags in the response of exports to changes in the level of real remuneration to exporters. The definitions of all variables and their sample means and simple correlation coefficients with the depen- dent variable are shown in Table IV-I. These last two items are shown for three different periods: (1) pre- minidevaluation: first quarter of 1964 to second quarter of 1968; (2) minidevaluations: second quarter of 1968 to second quarter of 1972; and (3) combined: first quarter of 1964 to second quarter of 1972. The methods, sources, and problems faced in collecting data for all variables are discussed in Appendix B. Below, a search is made for the models which show the best fit. This includes the test of a model with a geometric lag distribution and of models with simpler lagged forms concerning the response of exports to changes in the real remuneration to exporters. The method to test the effects of minidevaluations discussed in the first section of this chapter is applied to the best fit models. Testing of Competinngodels Equation 1 in Table IV-2 shows the estimation of Model (I) for 33 observations from the first quarter of 1964 1227 .meCH ooHum opmqupHuoz 02» >3 pouMHuoo muo3 mmsHm> umHHOO acouusu .AoEoocH pHuoz uOu xxoumv munOQEH oHuoz Hobou no ooHo> HowH or» no EroHpmooo mm. em. mm. mm.HH me.HH O~.HH .mmusuomuscms uo manomxo u0u mo>HucoocH HmomHu mo Ho>oH ecu monocmp eoch xoocH was no seuHomooq OO. HO. OO. HH.~ OH.~ 5O.~ ca.mmHuHooEEoo HHa u0u xmch ooHuQIonmoHonz monoum omuHca can mo on: >9 coHuMHmcH umHHoo new poumsnpm mm: uHsmou one one mpoom HoHuumspcw MOm xmch ooHumIonmOHonz :mHHHNmum mnu xn poumHump mm: mums oceanoxOImmonouom HmHonmo HmcHEoc one .coHumHucH uMHHop qu omumshpm manomxo HmHuu Imsch u0w oumu omcmnoonHmon was no xoch ecu mo EEuHummoq mH. I Ow. ON. I Ho.m OO.N HO.~ o.mmHqu0EEoo HHm uOu xmocH onuQImHmm ImHon3 moumum OOUHCD on» an meMHump muoz mosHo> umHHoo ucouusu .coHumunHmmMHo xmodu 30: o» mchuooom AmmunuomwocmEHEom ochsHome mousuomwscme wo muuoaxw m.HH~mum mo 05Ho> umHHOO accumcoo may no EEuHumOOH OO.H OO.H OO.H mn.> mm.n mm.n oox ooH omx ooH omx ooH on moH Nb .HO paw NO .uO pom mm .HO USN NO .uO USN NO .HO USN mm .MO USN new .MO OMH Imw .HO Uum loo .MO umH va .uO umH IOO .HO cum Ivm .HO umH oHndHum> one cam ux OOH cmo3uom coo: ucoHonmmou coHumHmunou wHQEHm oHooHom> pcm mammz mHQEmm . muCQHUwamonU COHUQHQHHOU .mcoHuHcHwoo .mmusuommscmx mo muuoaxm mo mmeHmc< :onmoummm cH pmmu mmHQMHum>II.HI>H mqmde 2128 .coHumecH Hmcuouxo cam HmcuoucH noon on pmumsnpm mH mw>Houmu umuuomxm on» awn» OUHMQ on» .EHOu mHnu :H xoch OUHuQ HMHuumdch OHMmmHon3 m.HHNmum um mumu omcmcoxo ommcousmleHonwo no xoocH u xao .xmch moHuc onmoHon3 (m: x .AmHmexo HOw .mooH>uom oHHnsmv moHnmpmnuIcoc xcmE mopsHocH soH23 xmocH ooHum umEsmcoo mzu no room uOumemp o>HumcumuHm on corn mpoom oHompmuu mo monud ecu nouuwo muoonon moHuHOOEEoo HHm u0w xoch ooHumIonmmHon3 mwumum pouHca ones .Epoo moooouoomHo mm. mm. HO. NH.H OH.~ OO.~ o .Lon . omxv OOH Ou Hosvm .mousuumMscmE mo muouuoaxo o» coHumumc:Emu um Home no xoocH no eroHumooq mm. mm. HO. NH.~ OH.~ OO.~ x moH .AcoHuosooum HmHuumsch :mHHH~mum mo conmoumwu ccouu IoEHu EOuw mHoapHmmuv coHu -6NHHHoo soHomooo poO sxope so. as. mm. I Oe.e- NO.O em.eHI omx 129 TABLE IV-2.--Regression Analysis to Explain the Behavior of Brazilian Exports of Manufactures (x Ordinary Least Squares Regressions With log Xlt 33 Quarterly Obser- vations from lst Quarter of 1964 to 2nd Quarter as the Dependent Variable; of 1972 (2nd Quarter 1964 deleted due to Unusual Political Events). Eq. 1 Eq. 2 Eq. 3 Eq. 4 Constant -21.837 -17.024 -16.058 -15.590 log X .969 2t ( 1.610) ( .119) log X .362 3t ( .368) ( .716) log X6t .872 .311 ( 1.514) ( .454) ( .141) ( .654) log x _ 1.028 .874 6(t 1) ( 2.097) ( 1.450) ( .045) ( .158) log x4t 2.370 2.021 1.908 1.837 ( 3.680) ( 5.887) ( 5.956) ( 5.100) ( .001) ( unopcomoo ocu wo osHm> poOOMH oru >3 coxmu mH oHnoHum> xuouocmmeo on» mo oomHm or» cons oHnmoHHcmo uoc mH umou cOmuoz IcHnuso one .uopuo has» :H >Ho>Huoommou .mucoHonwooo poumEHumo onu wo mHo>oH oocmonHcme on» can mosHm>Iu ocu one ucoHoHuuooo sumo mops: mononucoumm CH muonEs: one .HI>H oHnme cH ohm moHanum> on» no mcoHuHcHwoo one HeOH. ONNO. mOOO. mmm mOOO.Ov mOO0.0v NON. .mHm OHO.HOH NNO.mm NOO.H m Hem. ONO. OOH. NM ONO. «we. HON. Nm NN.O OH.O AmIon ooH OH.O ON.O III leIoOox OoH Oe.O Hm.O OOOO. I lmIoOox ooH NO.O H0.0 HOO. I ANIoOOx ooH mO.O mo.H OOO. I iHIoOox ooH ANOO. O AOOH. O lane. O reeN.H O loom.H O AONNO. IO no HH.H I NO.N I NNO. I HHH.H OO0.0N NNO. I x ooH AOOOO.OVO Ammo. O AOOO. O ANOO.m O ANHH.N O AOOO.H O AHIoOH men. mmm. HOe. x ooH Hma.H I Ome.O I NO.N Oee. I OOO.N I OOm.e nooomooo NNOH .uo ooN NNOH .no ocN OOOH .no ocN IOOOH .no pun IOOOH .uo pom IOOOH .uo pom HUm coHuoncm Hmm coHumnvm Adm :oHumzvm MOnm oouosoopO Eouw pouospopO Eoum pouospopO mcoHum>uomno Hm mcoHum>uomno OH mGOHum>uomno mH we coHumscm mm coHumscm 4m coHuoscm Um coHumscm mm coHumsvm 4m COHumavm .oHanum> ucopcomoo oru mm uHx OOH nuHB mconmoumom moumsvm umooq xuocHouo .Hoooz wmgnmouanpumHQ m ruH3 AuHxO mousuoowdcmz uo muuoaxm co mcoHuosHm>opHCH2 mo muoomwm uo umoeII.MI>H mqmce 137 The test of the null hypothesis that the 16 addi- tional observations (1968-1972) obey the same relation as the first 15 (1964-1968) now can be performed. [SSEC - SSEa + SSEb)]/k .186676 - (.068509 + .O77467)/3 F — (SSEa + SSEb)/(n + m-2k)= .145976/(31-6 =———:2::2;32 . -— = whereas F3,25,.10 = 2'32' Therefore, at the 10 percent level of significance, the null hypothesis of same relationship may be rejected; it may be concluded that the policy of mini-adjustments of the exchange rate made a significant difference in making exports of manufactures more responsive to the level of real export remuneration. But the 10 percent level of significance is not satisfactory. Searching for better fit and greater significance, models with simpler lagged forms, which also include the variable X are 4t’ tested below for the three different periods. Test of Minidevaluations with the Best Fitted Models The analysis of results examined so far indicate that the best explanation of exports of manufactures might be given by a variant of Model (II) above, with the deletion 138 of the proxy of industrial capacity utilization, XSt’ and with the consideration of some lag in the response of exports of manufactures to changes in the level of real remuneration to exporters, X6t' There are also indications of a structural shift in the behavior of exports as a result of minidevaluations. To test the existence of this shift, the following modified variants of Model (II) were esti— mated for the three periods (A, pre-minidevaluations; B, minidevaluations; and C, the combined one): log Xlt = 81 + 82 log X6t + 83 log X4t + Et’ (X) log X1t = 81 + 82 log x6(t-l) + 83 log X4t + Et' (XI) log Xlt = 81 + 82 log X6t + 83 log X6(t-l) + 84 log X4t + at. (XII) In Table IV-4, Equations 7A, 7B, and 7C correspond to Model (X) regressed respectively for periods A, B, and C, Equations 8A, 8B, and 8C to Model (XI), and Equations 9A, 9B, and 9C to Model (XII). Equations 7C, 8C, and 9C fit the quarterly data from 1964 to 1972 very well. All three yield R2 approxi- mately equal to .91 and a very high level of significance (Hw9HoC00 UOC mH uH .UN coHumscm mo mono or» CH eHCo mHodonou mo CoHuMHouuooouso o>HuHmoa mo oocomoum wouooHpCH oHumHumum Cemuox ICHnuso one .uoouo our» CH >Ho>HuoommoH .mucoHonmooo pouoEHumo one mo mHo>oH ooCMUHuHCmHm ocu OCo mosHm>Iu oCu oum uCoHuHuuooo sumo nopCs monoEUCouom CH muonesc one .HI>H oHnme CH oum moHnoHuo> HHo mo mcoHuHCHuop oCe .NNOH nouHMSU pCooomIIVOmH uouuosv umun uncoHuo>uomno mm nOpoHuom .memH uouumsc ocooomIImOmH nouuosv puHCu umCoHuo>uomno OH xwpoHuom .HmuCo>o HMUHuHHom ou osp pouoHop «OOH mo Housman pCooomO OOOH uouuodv ocooonIIVOmH uouumsv umHHw "wCoHuo>uomno OH"¢.poHuom 1139 NH.H OO.H OO.H OH.H «O.H NO.H NO.H OO.H OO.H .3.o mOOO.Ov OOOO.OV OOOO.OV mOO0.0v OOOO.OV OOOO.OV OOOO.OV OOOO.OV OOOO.OV .OHO OOO.OOH HOO.OO OOH.OH OO0.00H NOO.Om OON.ON NHO.OOH HOO.mm OH0.0H C OOO. ONO. OOO. OHO. OOO. NON. OOO. ONO. HOO. Nm NHO. OOO. NON. OHO. OOO. «ON. NHO. OOO. OON. NO AOOOO.OVO AOOO. O ANOO. O AOOOO.OVO ANOO. O AHOO. O AOOOO.OVO AOOO. O AHOO. O AONO.O O AOOH.H O ANOO.O O AONN.N O ANON.O O ANON.O O AHOO.O O AHOH.OHO AOON.O O no OOO.H NHH.O MOO.H HOO.N NO0.0 ONO.H HOH.N OmO.N OOO.H x OoH AmeO.H O LOOO. IO AHOO.H O LONO.N O LOHO. O AONO.H O AHIOOO OON. OOm. I OOO. OOO. Hoe. OOO. x OoH lNNm. O . AOOO. O ANHO. O ANNH. O AOON. O AOOH. O ANNO. O AONO.H O AONO. O AONO.H O ANHH.H O ANOO.H O no OOO. OOO.N Owe. mOO. OON.H NNO. x OoH HHO.OHI OOO.OOI ONO.OHI HHO.NHI OO.OOI ONO.OHI ONO.NHI OOO.ONI OOO.OHI oomomcoo oO .om OO .OO «O .om oO .om OO .om 4O .om uN .ou ON .om 4N .om .oHQMHum>u ucopCocoo on» no uHx moH nqu mConmouOom mouozvm umooq euoCHpuo .mHoOoz pouuHm umom on» CuH3 A Hxv mouduomwscmz no monocxm Co mCoHuooHo>opHCHz mo muuomum mo umoeII.VI>H mande 140 especially in Equations 7C and 8C. The coefficients of log X6(t-l) in Equations 8C and 9C were,respectively,more significant than that of log X6 in Equations 7C and 9C. t The high t values of the coefficients of Equation 8C could lead to the conclusion that this is the best model to explain the determinants of exports of manufactures. An interesting fact, however, was discovered in the investigation of whether a structural shift had taken place in the model from period A to period B as a result of the minidevaluations. Not only exports became more elastic with respect to both the current real remuneration to exporters (X6t) and world income (X but also X 4t) I had a more rapid effect on Xl during the period under 6 which the minidevaluations were in effect. This is clearly seen in the equations of periods A and B. All of the six equations pertaining to periods A and B present very high over-all significance ( F3'27’.05 - 2.96. For Equations 8A, BB,and BC: .1684 - (.0667 + .0565)/3 = .0452 x 21 .1237/27 .1232 3 ' F = .3669 x 9 = 3.30 > F 2.96. 3,27,.05 = For Equations 9A, 9B,and 9C: F _ .1665 - (.0645 + .0516)Z3 _ .0504 x 21 ‘ .1161/27 ‘ TIIEI 3 ' F=.4 = . = 341 x 2 3 91 > F3,27'.05 2.96. 142 The F test applied to all three models indicates that, at the 5 percent level of significance, the null hypo- thesis of same relationship for the two different periods may be rejected. Therefore, it may be concluded that the policy of minidevaluations made a significant difference in making exports of manufactures more responsive both to the level of real export remuneration and to the level of world income. Conclusion The regression analysis with quarterly data shows that minidevaluations had a positive effect on exports of manufactures. The most significant effect was to make these exports more responsive to changes in the level of real remuneration to exporters. The regression analysis with annual data, presented in Appendix C, fell short of supporting this hypothesis with strong conclusive evidence. Nevertheless, it also gave indications that exports of manufactures became more responsive to changes in the level of remuneration to exporters, both through changes in the real exchange rate and through changes in the level of fiscal incentives. CHAPTER V ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON EXPORTS OF BASIC PRODUCTS The data presented in Chapter III indicated that exports of most primary products performed relatively well during the period when the mini-adjustments of the exchange rate were in effect. The econometric analysis of these exports was limited because for most basic products only annual observations on both prices and values were available, and these were confined to the period 1964-1971. An aggregate export supply function for 28 basic products was estimated. For most of these products, Brazil's participation in world trade is rela- tively small, so that the international market price could be considered to be affected only mildly by Brazil's supply, and the foreign demand for them could be considered approximately as perfectly elastic. Because it is far from meeting this condition, coffee was excluded from these 28 basic products. Brazil produces about one-third of the world consumption of coffee. Coffee trade is also subject to unique peculiarities, 143 144 such as the Brazilian government's contribution quota (US$23.96 per exported bag of 60kg in 1972) and the regulations of the International Coffee Agreement. Further- more, since the production cycle of coffee lasts about five years, it is too early to study properly the effects of the new exchange rate policy on coffee exports. For some of the 28 products included in the following analysis--mainly cotton, cocoa, sugar, and iron ore--Brazil is a major, but not a dominant world supplier.1 The Model The following models were used to estimate the export supply of basic exports: + log X1t 81 82 log X2t + 83 log X3t + 84 log X4t + 87 X7t + at; (I) log X = B + 8 1t (II) log X + 6t 84 log X + 4t 87 X + e 6 7t t' where Xlt = exports of basic products other than coffee deflated by the world-trade price index; x2t = index of real exchange rate for exports of basic products other than coffee (nominal purchase exchange rate deflated by the Brazilian wholesale price index); lBrazil's share in international trade ranges about 5 percent for cotton, 9 percent for cocoa, 6 percent for sugar and less for other primary products. The country does not act as a large individual seller, however, for most primary commodities. There are many export agents who have a position which approximates that of perfect competitor in world trade. 145 X3t = price index for Brazil's exports of basic products other than coffee; X4t = proxy for world income; world imports deflated by the price index for world imports; X7t = annual average of the monthly percentage variation (without sign) in the real exchange rate for exports (X2t). (The number 7 was used because this variable is similar to X7t used in annual regressions for industrial exports); and X = index of real remuneration to exporters of 6t basic products other than coffee. It is the product of X times X . 2t 3t The supply of basic exports is considered as a function of the real remuneration to exporters, of the proxy for world income, and of the index of fluctuations in the real exchange rate. The greater the real remunera- tion to exporters (X6t)’ the greater should be the supply of exports (Xlt). Two factors affect the real remuneration to exporters: the index of real exchange rate for exports (x2t) and the price index for exports (X Model (I) 3t) ° tests the response of exporters to the separate behavior of these two indexes. Model (II) tests the response of exporters to the product of the two indexes. Both models are similar since log X6t = log (X2t ° X3t) = log X2t + log X3t Model (II) may be considered a superior formulation, however, because it is the final product, X that really 6t' affects the profitability of exporters, not just its 146 separate components X2t and X3t' formulations will permit the comparison of the significance, Testing the competing signs, and values of the coefficients of log X2 and log X3 t 6t' The proxy for world income, X4t' is t with those of log X also expected to have a positive effect on exports. The variable X the index of fluctuations in the real exchange 7t’ rate, enters the function as a qualitative variable. Appendix E illustrates how this variable depicts the effects of minidevaluations. Small fluctuations in the real exchange rate mean a low degree of exchange risk to the exporter. Therefore, the smaller the value of X7t' the greater should be the incentive to export. Models (I) or (II) differ from that used by Doellinger from nontraditional basic products (see Chapter III, page 84) with respect to some variables. He had included an index of production of ten primary products and found that good harvests tend to have a significant positive effect on exports. As a price variable, Doellinger had included only the real exchange rate, not the price index, of exports. No apprOpriate index or production for the 28 primary products could be found. An available index based on ten main products would take into account only about one-third of the value of exports of the 28 products. On the other hand, one may assume that the production index of agricultural goods is a function mainly of their price and of weather conditions. 147 It was not possible to use weather conditions as a variable, but the price of all 28 basic products, which included not only agricultural but also mineral and animal products, were available and were used in a weighted form. Further discussion of each variable and the data and measurement problems are presented in Appendix D. The Regression Results In view of the small number of observations avail- able one cannot expect high levels of significance for all individual coefficients. Their estimated values should not be seen as accurate elasticity values. First, Model (I) was run to test the separate effects of changes in the real exchange rate and in the export prices during the period 1964-1971. The result is Equation 1. log X = 6.5755 + .5464 10g X + .5674 log X 1t 2t 3t (.8187) (.6900) (.473 ) (.540 ) + 1.1716 log X4t - .0083 X7t' (2.2583) (*1.5756) ( .109 ) ( .213 ) (I) 8 Observations, F = 22.661 Significance .014 122 = .9680 '82 = .9250 D.W. = 2.31, does not indicate presence of autoregression. 148 The t values, and under them the significance values, are shown in parentheses under the respective coefficients. The regression was significant at the 1.0 percent level and presented an excellent fit (R2 =.925). All the coefficients had the correct theoretical signs. Interest- ingly, the elasticity of exports of basic products with respect to the real exchange rate, X2t' was exactly the same as that found by Doellinger for nontraditional basic products (see Chapter III, page 84, .054).2 The elas- ticity with respect to the price of exports was also low and approximately the same, 0.57. Both were not very significant, however. Greater significance was shown by the elasticity coefficient of the proxy for world income. Its value was slightly higher than unity. Wide fluctua- tions in the real exchange rate had a negative impact on the growth of exports, as indicated by the sign of X7t, but the significance of the coefficient, although greater than that of log X and log X3t’ did not permit permit 2t a definite conclusion. The best fit was obtained with Model (II): log Xlt = -5.571 + .5485 log X6t + 1.1828 log X4t (1.4514) (6.4229) ( .220 ) ( .003 ) - .0082 X7t (-1.9238) ( .127 ) (II) lDoellinger's regression, however, was on quarterly data. 149 8 Observations, F = 40.4975 Significance .002 R2 = .9681 8'2 = .9442 D.W. = 2.31, no autoregression. Equation (II), in spite of the small sample size, presented an excellent fit and a higher coefficient of determination (R2 = .9681) than that obtained by Doellinger's best fit model (R2 = .85) for nontraditional exports. Exports of basic products proved to be inelastic-~the coefficient was 0.55--with respect to changes in the level of real remuneration to exporters. The elasticity coeffi- cient of the proxy for world income was highly significant (.003), and its value was 1.2. Finally, at the 12 percent level of significance the coefficient of X7t indicated that the greater the level of fluctuations in the real exchange rate, the smaller the rate of growth in exports of basic products. The simple correlation coefficient between X7t and log X1t size of the coefficient of X7t is not so important and was expected to be small because it related a log value during 1964-1971 was -.78. The which had small range, from 8.66 to 9.02, with a nonlog value, which had a much greater range, from 0.85 to 150 14.1.2 Its negative sign and its significance-~quite reasonable for only 8 observations--confirmed one main hypothesis tested in this dissertation: The policy of mini-adjustments in the exchange rate had a positive effect on the Brazilian exports of basic products. Conclusion The very small number of observations available has limited the quality of the above econometric analysis. Nevertheless, it may be concluded that the policy of mini-adjustments in the exchange rate has had a positive impact on exports of primary products. 2The following coefficients were foundwwhen X1 was run against the same variables in a nonlog form for the same period 1964-1971: X = 9,299,037.1953 + 4,253,861.1628 X + .0044 X 1t 6t 4t (1.2992) (7.0502) ( .264) ( .002 ) - 9,873,345.71 X7 (-1.3410) ( .251 ) Overall F = 38.0522 Significance .002 R2 = .9661 132 = .9408 D.W. = 2.24 In this nonlog form the variable X7 has a large coeffi- cient, but it becomes less significant than in the log form. CHAPTER VI THE EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON BRAZILIAN IMPORTS Since Brazil's demand for imports constitutes only about 1 percent of world exports, it may be assumed that the country faces an infinitely elastic export supply curve. The exchange risk that is inherent in a system of sharp and unpredictable adjustments in the exchange rate may have a negative influence on the volume of imports. Importers are always ready to take advantage of profit- able opportunities provided by an occasional overvalued domestic currency. The risks of devaluation, however, may jeopardize the normal development of imports. For example, in case of products which need to be ordered well in advance of the shipment time, so that they can be produced according to specific requirements, the insta- bility of the exchange rate constitutes a nuisance that might discourage trade. The objective of this chapter is to find out to what extent imports were affected by the policy of mini- adjustments in the exchange rate. The demand for imports is 151 152 a function mainly of the relation between internal and external prices, of national income, and of import barriers. Important modifications occurred with respect to trade barriers just prior to the institution of the minidevalua- tions. In the beginning of 1965 the cost for import credits (compulsory deposits) was significantly reduced. In March 1967 a general tariff reform lowered effective protection of manufacturing industry from 98 percent to 52 percent on the average for all sectors, and from a range of 10-333 percent to a range of 10-139 percent. The aims of the reform were to intensify price competition from abroad, to force import-substituting industries to economize on costs, and to facilitate an export drive by these industries.1 Although at the end of 1968 tariffs were increased again, they were still lower than the ones that existed prior to 1967. The price and income elas- ticities of import demand are expected to be greater after the lowering of tariffs because the prior tariff levels practically prohibited imports of several goods. This makes the task of identifying the effects of the minide- valuations more difficult. As shown below, the import liberalization policy has made import demand expand con— siderably more than production or income in the past five years. After a brief analysis of imports during the period 1See Donges, Brazil's Trotting Peg. 153 1968-1972, econometric models will be used to examine to what extent they were affected by new exchange policy. Brazilian Imports Since 1968 From 1968 to 1972 Brazilian imports of merchandise had an average growth rate of about 23 percent per year, much greater than that of the Gross Domestic Product (about 10 percent). This growth was exceptional compared to the previous two decades. The proportion of imports over GDP (in current cruzeiros), which had reached the record low of 5 percent in 1965, surpassed the 8 percent level in 1971. Machinery and equipment, and chemical, mineral, and metal products were the main commodity cate- gories that led this growth. Imports have had a key role in the process of fixed capital formation in Brazil. In the past years machinery and equipment constituted about 35 percent of total imports. (See Tables F-l to F-S in Appendix F.) I Since 1968 Brazil has not experienced a shortage in its capacity to pay for imports, despite trade deficits in 1971 and 1972. This was mainly due to the concommitant expansion in exports and the increase in the net inflow of capital at the exceptional average yearly growth of 57 percent (1968-1971). (See Table F-7 in Appendix F.) 154 Econometric Analysis of Import Behavior The Model The following model was used to describe Brazilian import behavior: log X = + 1 81 log X where: X1 = total Brazilian imports of merchandise in constant cruzeiros of 1949; X2 = Gross Domestic Product in constant cruzeiros of 1949; X3 = index of real import exchange rate (nominal import index deflated by the ratio of the Brazilian wholesale price index over the U.S. wholesale price index) adjusted for import barriers, such as tariffs, auction fees, and so forth; and at = disturbance term. Observations of variables X1 and X2 were available only on an annual basis. Therefore, the sample size to test the period of minidevaluations was very small. The index of real import exchange rate, which was adjusted both for dollar inflation and for import barriers, was taken from the work of Joel Bergsman.2 Eighteen annual observations, from 1954 to 1971, were available. 2Bergsman, "Foreign Trade Policy in Brazil." Bergsman had calculated 17 annual indexes. This author estimated the 1971 index following his method. Bergsman's adjustment for tariffs considers the nominal rather than the effective rate of protection. This has an important implication discussed at the end of this chapter. 155 The demand for imports is expected to respond positively to changes in real national income and negatively to changes in the index of real exchange rate adjusted for tariffs, and so forth. Since the policy of the government in certain periods seemed to be one of facilitating imports whenever the capacity to pay for them was growing, and since the net inflow of capital has been particularly associated with imports, the capacity to import also should be considered as a variable that might determine changes in imports. By capacity to import goods, X4, is meant:3 >< ll CFP - S, where CFP = PPX - A + NIC 4 X4 = PPX - A + NIC - S, where PPX = X (MPI/XPI) X4 = X(MPI/XPI) - A + NIC - S where: CFP = capacity of foreign payments. S = service (commercial and noncommercial) receipts-service payments PPX = purchasing power of exports A = amortizations NIC = net inflow of capital MPI = import price index XPI = export price index. 3This is the definition of capacity to import goods currently used by the Brazilian monetary authorites (see Table F-7, Appendix F). 156 In view of this expectation the following model was tested: log x = 81 + 8 (II) 1 log X2 + 83 log X3 + 84 log X4 + e 2 t’ where X1, X2, X3, and e have the same meaning as is in t Model (I), and X4 is the capacity to import. Here, however, total imports (X1) and real GDP (X2) were measured in con- stant dollars since the capacity to import was measured more accurately in dollars than in cruzeiros. A consistent series of observations for the capacity to import, as defined above, was available only for 13 years, from 1959 to 1971. (See Table F-7 in Appendix F.) To examine the effects of minidevaluations on imports, different approaches were followed. First, both Models (I) and (II) were tested for period A, 1954 to 1968 for (I) and 1959-1968 for (II), and for period B, which includes the three years 1969-1971, during which the minidevaluations were in effect.4 Alternatively, a dummy variable, D, representing the policy of minidevaluations, was included in modified versions of Models (I) and (II). The problems involved in the different tests will be dis- cussed with the presentation of results. The data used in the estimation Model (I) is shown in Table VI-l and Figure VI-l, whereas that used to estimate Model (II) is shown in Table VI-2 and Figure VI-2. y 4About one-third of 1968 also should be excluded from period A but this was not possible with annual data. TABLE VI-l.--Data for Estimation of Braz 157 Function (Model I)- il's Import Total Imports In Constant Cruzeiros of Gross Domestic Produce in Constant Cruzeiros Index of Real Import Exchange Rate (nominal import index deflated by Brazilian W.P.I./ U.S. W.P.I.) Adjusted for Tariffs, Auction Year 1949 of 1949 Fees, etc. X1 X2 X3 1954 24.5 318.2 154 1955 23.7 340.0 194 1956 23.6 350.8 211 1957 25.4 379.1 270 1958 27.0 408.3 249 1959 30.7 431.1 290 1960 29.2 472.9 243 1961 31.4 521.6 321 1962 35.0 549.0 364 1963 30.8 557.5 329‘ 1964 25.6 573.8 329 1965 26.3 589.5 288 1966 32.3 619.6 203 1967 34.1 649.2 165 1968 43.8 709.7 169 1969 47.8 773.6 190 1970 56.3 847.2 187 1971 69.6 942.9 183 Sources: Relatorio 1971, CACEX, Banco do Brasil. 1: 2 3 February 1971). ° Conjuntura Econdmica, 26 (November 1972). : Joel Bergsman, "Foreign Trade Policy in Brazil," U.S. AID (unpublished study, 158 .elm oHnme oom “ x .AHNOH Onnsnnom .Oosum OoCmHHnsmCSO QHC .m.D =.HHNmum CH OUHHom opmue COHouoms .CmEmmHom HoOO “mx .ANOOH HonEo>on Om .moHEOCoom musuCCnCoo ”mx pcm Hx "moousom OOH.v OOH 0.000.0m OOO.m HOOH OOO.N OOH H.OOO.Nm Omm.m OOOH ehv.~ OOH O.mm0.0m OOO.H OOOH OOO.H OOH O.Hmm.e~ >OO.H OOOH NMH.H OOH 0.00N.ON OHv.H OOOH mov.H mom «.OOO.¢N Oom.H OOOH emm.H OON e.hmm.mm MOO OOOH OON.H Omm N.OO~.NN ONH.H OOOH NOO.H Omm m.va.H~ Hom.H OOOH OOO.H vOm m.OHm.HN Nvm.H NOOH OOm.H Ham O.Hmm.O~ ovm.H HOOH OHO mvm 0.00m.OH wOm.H OOOH HNH.H OON 0.0me.OH mvm.H OOOH 6X mx Nx HX mooHHm .ouo .moom mooHHm moOHHm moo» OO\OOOH COHuosm .mmmHHoe eO\mOOH OO\OOOH um um unodEH How pouanO< um pospoum muHOQEH on OOHonomo H.H.d.3 .m.s oHumosoo O.HHnmnm O.HHNnnm \.H.d.z onHHHNnnm mmono Hmom On ooonHOoo xoOCH uuomEH HMCHEOCO ouom omcmnoxm unomEH Hmom mo xoOCH .HHH Hooon COHHOCCO unanH m.HHNon mo COHumEHuwm How oHMOII.NIH> mqmde 900- BOG-H 700-H Gross Domestic Product in Constant Cruzeiros of 000-1 1949 303-4 Index 400.H 400 300 — 300 .200—I 20° . . 100 100.. Real Exchange Rate Adjusted for Dollar Inflation and Import Barriers (in terms of index) 90-- 80- 70-- 60- 50- 40-d 30.1 20-— Total Imports in Constant Cruzieros of 1949 10.4 ITIIIrIIITTII 1 1 5 9 6O 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 I l 1954 55 -6 57 58 Lil Ffirpire VI-1.-—Brazil's Imports in Constant Cruzeiros of 1949, GDP in Constant Cruzeiros of 1949, and the Real Exchange Rate Adjusted for Dollar Inflation and Import Barriers. 160 Index 400 H Index of real import exchange rate adjusted for 300 dollar inflation and import barriers. q 200«- 100 1 I I if 17 I l’ I I" f 17 I II 1 U.S. $ millions 550,000" 40,000-( Real gross domestic product at 1965/1967 prices 30,000-4 20.000-( 10,000-( I U l' I I I 1 I I I I I ’T Capacity to import 4.000-1 at 1965/1967 prices \2’ 3,000- " Imports at 1965/1967 prices 2,000“ 1,000-- r I I l T I I I T l I I l 1959 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 Figure VI—2.--Brazil's Imports, GDP, Capacity to Import and Real Exchange Rate Adjusted for Dollar Inflation and Import Barriers. 161 Regression Results Model (I) regressed for periods A and B gave the following results: A. 15 Observations, from 1954 to 1968: log X1 = .2608 + .5427 log X2 - .1061 log X3 (1a) (4.4921) {-.9608) ( .001 ) ( .356 ) The numbers in parentheses under each coefficient are the t-values and the significance levels of the estimated coefficients, respectively. F = 10.1101 Significance .003 R2 = .6276 §2 = .5655 D.W. = 1.09, not conclusive as to presence of autoregression SSE = .0292. a B. 18 Observations, from 1954 to 1971: log X1 = .1466 + .8190 log X2 - .2418 log X3 (lb) (7.4574) (-1.8818) (<0.0005) ( .079) = 32.2164 Significance <0.0005 F R2 = .8112 EZ = .7860 162 D.W. = .65 dL,2,18,.01 = 0.80 dU,2,18,.01 = 1'26 indicates the presence of autoregression. SSEb = .0579. Both the level of overall significance and the degree of fit substantially improved with the addition of the three observations. The elasticity coefficients of imports (X1), both with respect to GDP (X2) and to the real exchange rate adjusted for tariffs, and so forth, (X3) more than doubled when the years 1969-1971 were added to the regression. Still, their values in both equations indicate very low elasticities. Changes in X3 were not even significant in determining the level of exports in period A. This is an indication that the level of tariffs were so high and prohibitive that changes in relative prices did not affect imports significantly. The low, but still very significant, GDP elasticity coefficient indicates that the import-substituting policies pursued by the government, especially from 1954 until the tariff reform caf 1967, substantially limited the response of imports to 5When the disturbances are autoregressive, the least-square estimators are unbiased and consistent, but they are not efficient or assymtotically efficient. The respective variances are biased, and as a result, the tests of significance to the regression coefficients might lead to incorrect statements. Kmenta, Elements of Econo- metrics, pp. 278-81. 163 increases in real national income.6 With the application of the Chow or Fisher test at the 5 percent level of signi- ficance, it may be affirmed that a structural shift has taken place in the regression equation after 1968: F _ SSEb ‘ SSEa/m = .0579 - .029313 _ ‘ SSEa/n - k .0292/15 - 3 3.93 >F3Ilz'005 = 3.49. In addition to the lowering of tariffs, the policy of minidevaluation also might have contributed to the increase in the elasticity coefficients which have character- ized this structural shift. This test, however, does not permit a distinction between the two possible causes. Minidevaluations Represented By a Dummy Variable A significant result was obtained with the following modified version of Model (I): log X1 = 81 + aD + 82 log X2 + 83 log X3 + + e (I) D log X3 t 0‘3 6The low elasticity values which were found contrast sharply with the U.S. income elasticity for import demand for manufactures of +2.35 and with the relative price elas- ticity of -4.7, as found by Kreinin for 43 quarterly obser- vations from 1954 to 1964. Mordechai E. Kreinin, Alterna- tive Commercial Policies-~Their Effect on the American Ecoggmy (East Lansing: Michigan State University, 1967), p. . 164 In this formulation the dummy variable D is used to allow both for a differential intercept and for a differ- ential elasticity coefficient for X3, the real exchange rate adjusted for tariffs and so forth. The dummy variable repre- sents the policy of minidevaluations. It takes the values of zero from 1954 to 1967, of 0.34 in 1968, and of one from 1969 to 1971. The result, for 18 observations, was: log X1 = .3167 + 9.5954 D + .4030 log X 2 ( 1.8266) (3.2845) ( .091 ) (.006) + .0237 log X3 - 4.1362 D log X3 (1.2182) (-1.7924) ( .831 ) ( .096 ) (II) F = 38.53 Significance <0.0005 R2 = .9222 82 = .8983 D.W. = 1.24 d = 0.71 L,3,18,.01 dU,3,18,.01 = 1'42 not conclusive as to presence of autoregression. Equation (II) was highly significant and showed a goodness of fit much greater than that of Equation (lb)-- R2 = .92 for Equation (I) compared to .79 for Equation 165 (1b). The coefficient of log X2 was again significant but low, indicating an inelastic income demand for imports. The dummy coefficient for the intercept was significant at the 9 percent level and showed a substantial differential in the function for the minidevaluation period. Changes in the real exchange rate adjusted for tariffs, and so forth, were not significant before 1968--the coefficient of log X was low and had the incorrect theoretical sign. 3 But a substantial change occurred during the period of minidevaluations. The coefficient of D log X3 was -4.14, had the correct sign, and was significant at the 10 per- cent level. One must be cautious, however, in interpreting the dummy variable. It represents, indeed, the period of minidevaluations, but this period almost coincided with the one during which lower and less prohibitive taxes came into effect. Therefore, the only possible conclusion is that a shift has taken place in the basic import func- tion since 1968. Whether or not the minidevaluations contributed to it cannot yet be affirmed. 166 The Inclusion of the Capacity to Import as an Independent Variable Model 01) regressed for periods A and B7 gave the following results: A. 10 Observations, from 1959 to 1968: log X1 = 7.130 + .1399 .log X - .1920 log X 2 3 (8.9896) (-1.531) ( .024 ) ( .177) + .1118 16g x4 (2a) (.5844) F = 5:455 Significance .038 R2 = .7317 82 = .5976 D.W. = 1.69, no autoregression. SSEa = .0110 B. 13 Observations, from 1959 to 1971: lob X1 = 3.4286 + .1503 log X2 - .1343 10g X3 (2.7911) (-.9408) ( .021 ) ( .371 ) + .4924 log X4 (2b) (5.248) ( .001) 7 Note that periods A and B have a smaller number of observations in this case compared to the regressions with Model (I). Another difference is that here the values of X1, X2, and X4 were in constant dollar figures instead of constant cruzeiros. 167 F = 27.9924 Significance <0.0005 R2 = .903 82 = .8707 D.W. = 2.06, no autoregression. SSEb = .0223 The equation gained substantially in significance and in goodness of fit when the three additional observa- tions were added. Imports in both periods A and B had a low but highly significant elasticitycoefficient with respect to GDP (X2). The elasticity coefficient with respect to the real exchange rate adjusted for tariffs, and so forth, (X3), was not significant in A and even less so in B, where it presented a lower value. The elasticity coefficient with respect to the capacity to import was only significant when the period 1969-1971 was added to the first ten observations. Its value increased from .11 to .49. Imports also were inelastic with respect to the capacity to import. In the case of Equations (2a) and (2b) the application of the Chow or Fisher test did not indicate that a structural shift took place in the para- meters after 1968: F = (SSEb ’ SSEa)/m = (.0223 - .0110)/3 sssa/n - E’ ‘76110/10 - 4 F = 2.05 < F3’6'.05 = 4.76 Care, however, must be used in interpreting the results of Equations (2a) and (2b). ‘The estimated 168 coefficients, especially that of log X3, might be unreliable due to the fact that several components of the capacity to import are dependent upon the level of the real exchange rate and also were affected, in different degrees, by the policy of minidevaluations.8 This is particularly true of exports, as examined in previous chapters, and of capital inflows and services, as will be seen below (see Table F-7 in Appendix F). Dummy Variable Used Again In an attempt to isolate the effect of the mini- devaluations and the effect of changes in the real exchange rate adjusted for tariffs, and so forth, on changes in imports, a dummy variable was introduced to allow both for a differential intercept and for a differential coefficient of log X3. The dummy takes again the values of zero from 1954 to 1967, of .034 in 1968, and of one from 1969 to 1971. The result for 13 observations from 1959 to 1971 was: log X1 = 7.228 + 12.7332 D + .1317 log X2 - .0260 log X3 (6.986) (2.7685) (-.1948) ( .111) ( .028 ) ( .851 ) - 5.5091 D log X3 + .0645 log X4 (-l.806) (.2960) ( .114) (.776 ) (III) 8This is a problem caused by a certain degree of multicollinearity. See Kmenta, Elements of Econometrics, p. 389. 169 F = 23.2036 Significance <0.0005 R2 = .9431 '82 = .9025 D.W. = 1.63, no autoregression. Equation (III) was highly significant and its goodness of fit was the best among all equations used to test the behavior of imports. In this formulation the coefficient of log X2 changes in GDP) was again low, but significant at the 2 percent level. The coefficient of log X4 (changes in import capacity) became very low and insignificant. A significant differential at the 11 percent level occurred both with the intercept and with the elas- ticity coefficient of the real exchange rate adjusted for tarrifs, and so forth. Indeed, log X3, which did not have a coefficient significantly different from zero prior to the minidevaluations, showed a highly elastic coefficient of -5.5 for the period after 1968. The fact that the capacity to import is dependent upon the real exchange rate might make these coefficients unreliable. But there is no doubt that there has been an important shift in import behavior since 1968. It is difficult to conclude whether its main cause was the lowering of tariffs to less prohibitive levels of whether minidevaluations also con- tributed to it, or both. However, if the effective, rather than the nominal, protection is considered, one might reach different con- clusions. The effective rate of protection is the 170 percentage increase in domestic value added made possible by the tariff structure compared to a situation under free trade. Joel Bergsman's calculations, as shown in Table VI-3, indicates that although product protection since January 1969 has been much lower than before March 1967, the current levels of effective protection are not so much lower. Especially for manufactured goods, which consti- tuted more than two—thirds of Brazilian imports in the past five years, effective protection since January 1969 has been only a few points below the pre-March 1967 level. Therefore, the lower nominal tariffs on the post-January 1969 period may have had only a minor impact on their "prohibitive" character.9 Accordingly, the shift in the Brazilian import function that occurred after 1968 must also be attributed to the minidevaluations. Conclusion The regression analysis showed that a significant shift in the parameters of the Brazilian import function took place with the advent of the minidevaluation policy. Imports became more responsive to income change and, especially, to changes in the real exchange rate adjusted 9It must be noted, however, that consumer demand is affected by nominal rather than by effective protection. Thus the change in the "prohibitive" character of the tariffs might have been quite relevant as the product protection for all goods changed from .46 before March 1967 to 0.22 after January 1969 (see Table VI—3). 171 for dollar inflation, tariffs, auction fees, and other trade barriers. This shift in the parameters of the import function had two direct causes: the lowering of the import tariffs and the policy minidevaluations. The first made some imports nonprohibitive and therefore more responsive to income and relative price changes. The second diminished the exchange rask caused by wide and unpredictable changes in the official exchange rate, and, because of this, also contributed to making imports more responsive to relative price changes. It was not possible, statistically, to distinguish the weight of these two causes. 172 00.0 00.0 00. 00.0 00.0 00. 0000006600268 was mnmeflum 004 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00. 0000006600088 000 00.0- 00.0- 00. 00.0- 00.0- 00. 0008000 000 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 06006000-062 Hmfidmfioo Hmnuo 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 0066660 006 060600>mm 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00. 00000600 0000 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00066000 06850060 00.0- 00.0- 00. - 00.0- 00.0 00. 006600006 006006600 00.0 00.0 00. 00.0 00.0 00. 006000662 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 00. 0600006506600 06>60-000m 00.0 00.0- 00. 00.0 00.0 00. 0606006806020 06>60-360 00.0- 00.0- 00. - 00.0- 00.0- 00. - 000002 00.0- 00.0- 00. 00.0 00.0- 00. 020nm0m paw musuasownmfl HNmH mwma DOD hmma 3mm udmmmum mmmH UGO Emma th mHOuumm MO mQDOHO -0000 060 -0000 00000 -0000 -0000 :60 -0000 00004 -0000 GOflHUQHOHm 0>HHU®MMW coauomuoum poscoum m.cmEmmumm HmOH .Hhmatmmma .GOHumEHumm .0000000000 m>0uommmm 066 c00uomuoum 0020000 umz-.m-0> m0m¢e 173 AD .0 usmcfl so mmxmu mmfioxm n . u can .mmo0um .0 usmcfl so mmaumu u Hp mpmuu 000w .n uospoum mo #0:: one n0 n moscoum on common 0 usmcw mo 050m> u ..m .n nonconm so mmwumu u .p 000:3 :0 .00 . u +0an0.M~ In0 H flu ”mm pmumHsoamo m0 cofiuomuoum m>0uommwm .0 ..m I .u .mmflcflmnsm 00 .mmxmu whomxm .GOHuomuoum mo woodman may :0 pmmcmnucs mbmuu mo mocmHmn Gnu cflmucflmfi @0503 £0033 mumn umzu mm cwcwmmp m0 mumu mmcmcoxm mwmuu 000m 039 .wumu mmcmzoxw mpmuu 000m mo mmmucmoumm "cofluomuoum umz .Aanma mumsunwm .>Usum Umgmfldfldacsv QHAN omoD ..efiflNM-Hm CHM \flUHHOnw QGMHB CWHQHOM: 0CMEmmHmm HmOH; ”mo-Hgom CHAPTER VII EFFECTS OF THE SYSTEM OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON SERVICES, CAPITAL MOVEMENTS, AND FOREIGN INDEBTEDNESS This chapter will examine the nature of capital movements and the foreign indebtedness position of Brazil in recent years. It will attempt to identify the influence of the system of frequent small exchange rate adjustments on those items. To complete the analysis of the country's foreign sector, it also will briefly describe the major trends that have characterized the behavior of services in the past 25 years, especially during the period of minidevaluations. Effects of Minidevaluations on Capital Movements The policy of minidevaluations has had two major impacts on capital movements. First, it has substantially diminished destabilizing short-term capital movements which previously had been harmful to the value of the cruzeiro. Second, along with other measures, it has 174 175 constituted a necessary condition for an open economy and for the exceptional recent influx of foreign capital.1 Under the old system of occasional large devalua- tions at fairly long intervals, huge financial speculative movements were made whenever a sharp change was expected in the foreign exchange rate. With running inflation, the longer the interval between devaluations, the greater would be the problem around the time of expected devaluation. Financiers, and people in general, anticipating the change would convert overvalued cruzeiros into foreign currencies. They would wait out the devaluation and then buy back the cruzeiros at the new rate, thus realizing a windfall gain in the amount of the devaluation. Just after a large devaluation people could be reasonably assured that no other change in the pegged exchange rate would occur, in, say, the next six months. They could then buy bills of exchange and gain the nominal interest prevailing in Brazil (20 percent per semester was common during 1960-1967). When people expected a new devaluation they again could convert their money into foreign currencies. This speculation- devaluation cycle led to periodic intense pressures on the credit market. Funds which normally would serve to finance productive activities would be temporarily diverted to buy foreign currencies. 1This section profited from the analyses of Lira, "Cruzeiro, O Preco Exato da Moeda"; Tyler, "Exchange Rate Flexibility"; Donges, Brazil's Tropting Peg; and Bracher, "Sistema Cambial de Taxa Flexivel." 176 Several types of exchange controls were imposed from time to time to prevent such speculative operations. The pressure continued to exist, however, as evidenced by the large differential between the official and black market value of the exchange rate which prevailed through- out the sixties until the beginning of the minidevaluations in August 1968. The differential varied from 15-20 percent from 1960 to 1968, to 60 to 100 percent in 1963 and 1964. Although no published data on black market rates during the period of minidevaluationsane available, interviews disclosed that these rates, in general, have varied less than 10 percent from the official rate since August 1968. The new exchange rate procedure, coupled with the interest rate policy pursued by the government, has made the purchase of foreign exchange for the sole purpose of gaining from devaluation unprofitable. The monetary authorities have been careful to keep the average rate of devaluation below the differential between internal and foreign interest rates. This differential has been about two percentage points per month and the rate of devaluation slightly over one percent per month. Since the internal rate of interest has exceeded the external level by more than the devaluation rate, there has been no incentive for _ 2See Conjuntura Econ6mica, 26 (November 1972), supplement, p. 34. The series of data on the black market rates is not complete, and it does not cover the period of minidevaluations. 177 Brazilians to invest abroad. The risk element involved in the adjustment interval, which has varied from 14 to 80 days, has made short-run speculative operations even less desirable. Table VII-1 shows that the differential annual yields between some selected domestic and foreign securi- ties has, in general, been greater than the annual cruzeiro devaluation during the period of minidevaluations. This has been true for the differential return between a Brazilian bill of exchange--an almost riskless security-- and the London Euro-Dollar interest rate. Unfortunately, no dataane available on a monthly basis to evaluate the effects of the minidevaluation policy on short-run speculative flows. The annual reports of the Banco Central do Brazil have stated, however, that speculative short-run movements against the cruzeiro have substantially diminished since August 1968. On the other hand, the minidevaluations, along with other important economic and political measures, have created the condi- tions for an exceptional influx of capital into Brazil in the past five years. Factors Which Have Influenced the Influx of Capital An examination of the several financial reforms and political and economic events which have affected the net movement of capital into Brazil is necessary in order 178 TABLE VII-1.--Differential Yields on Internal and External Securities Compared to Devaluation Rates. Annual Percentage Rates 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 Adjustable Brazilianl Treasury Bill (ORTN)143.3 22.8 24.0 27.1 23.7 Bill of Exchange2 (letra de cambio) 31.8 30.3 30.5 30.3 29.2 Us Treasury Bill3 5.3 6.7 6.4 4.3 3.7 Euro Dollar London Interest Rate4 6.4 9.8 8.5 6.6 5.2 ORTN minus US Treasury Bill 38.0 16.1 17.6 22.8 20.0 ORTN minus Euro Dollar Rate 36.9 13.0 15.5 20.5 18.5 Bill of Exchange minus US Treasury Bill 26.5 20.5 24.1 26.0 25.5 Bill of Exchange minus Euro Dollar Rate 25.4 20.5 22.0 23.7 24.0 Cruzeiro Devaluations 40.9 13.7 13.8 13.8 10.4 Source: 1 j ORTN carry a lZ-month maturity. from December to December. 2 Boletim, Banco Central do Brasil, F1nanc1al Statistics, IMF.‘ and International Return shown is Bill of Exchange of 6-month maturity, yearly rams After 1971 maturity considered is 360 days. taken in a Average tender rate for 3-month U.S. Treasury Bill. 4Average of daily quotations for 3-month deposits. Cruzeiro devaluation from December of the previous year to December of the stated year. is due to two large devaluations decreed in January and The high rate for 1968 August of that year, just before the beginning of the mini- devaluations. 179 to properly evaluate the specific influence of the mini- devaluation policy. First, important changes have occurred in the interest rate policy and capital markets. Real interest rates, due to legal restrictions, had become increasingly negative from 1960 to 1964 as the rate of inflation accelerated. Beginning in 1965 monetary correction to adjust for price changes was instituted and was extended to main financial instruments as part of the gradual approach to curb inflation. As a result, real interest rates became increasingly positive after 1966.3 Second, numerous measures were undertaken to bolster the development of the Brazilian stock market. Income tax deduction for stock purposes, the exemption of capital gains from taxation, the participation of the government in various ways, and the resurgence of Brazil's economic growth resulted in an unprecedented stock market boom from 1967 to 1971. The BV index of price for stocks listed on the Rio de Janeiro exchange increased by over 16 times from December 1967 to December 1971. The increase was exceptionally accelerated in the first semester of 1971, during which the index rose by 212 percent. 3See Leif Christoffersen, "Taxas de Juro e a Estrutura de um Sistema de Bancos Comerciais em Condicdes Inflacionérias," Revista Brasileira de Economia, 23 (June 1969); and Tyler,fiExchange Rate Flexibility." 180 Third, the monetary authorities have promulgated several regulations to provide mechanisms to channel short-term and medium-term foreign credit to Brazilian firms through the commercial banking system.4 Both national and foreign firms have increasingly acquired short- and medium-term loans abroad. Foreign firms have taken the lead in this practice, and many of the loans have been from parent company to subsidiary. As a result of some administrative regulations and of the favorable foreign investment climate, many foreign subsidiaries have brought money into Brazil as loans rather than having it registered as foreign investment. Fourth, the political regime since 31 March 1964 has played a major role in providing the most favorable climate for foreign investment. The importance of this factor is particularly notable when it is realized that few countries in Latin America, Africa, and Asia have had stable political and economic conditions in recent years. This, of course, has limited the opportunities for profitable investments by those who have surplus capital 4The main regulations are: (1) Resolution 63 of the Central Bank (August 1967) for loans granted for a term determined at the time of application (12 to 36 months); (2) Law 1431, which provides financing for a minimum of six months with no established maximum term, but which is dependent upon Central Bank approval; and (3) SUMOC Instruction 289, which allowed loans for periods of 180 to 360 days and which could be extended under Law 1431 at the discretion of the Central Bank. Instruction 289 was revoked in October 1972. 181 available in the developed countries. Brazil, since 1964, has been ruled by officers of the armed forces, who with the help of skilled civilian technicians, have been attempting to promote the fastest possible development under a mixed capitalist system. Political democracy has been kept at a very low level, and dissent has been firmly repressed. The government, with firm control of the media, has been successful in maintaining a tranquil business environment, which, coupled with the formidable economic opportunities in Brazil, has attracted foreign investors. Finally, the minidevaluation policy has substan- tially diminished the exchange rate risk for those involved in international financial operations. The initiation and expansion of large investment projects by foreign companies have become less dependent on changes in the level of the exchange rate. Also, there has been less risk of being suddenly subject to strict foreign exchange controls as a result of worsening disequilibrium in the balance of payments, a common situation in the early sixties. These factors have resulted in an exceptional upsurge of capital flow into Brazil, as shown in Table VII-2. Since 1968 the total influx has been increasing at a compounded rate of more than 38 percent per year. Esti- mates for 1972 show that the influx in that year was twice that of 1971 and more than seven times that of 1967. 182 Direct private investment from abroad increased at a compounded rate of over 20 percent from 1968 to 1972. The sum of direct investments in the period 1968-1972 was two-and-a-half times greater than that of the period 1963- 1967. The most dramatic rise, however, has been in loans and financing. From 1968 to 1971 about 25 percent of these funds came from the Interamerican Development Bank, USAID, World Bank, Eximbank, and International Financial Corporation, organizations which, since 1964, have been particularly supportive of the Brazilian development effort.5 The remaining 75 percent of loans and financing, a proportion that has been increasing in recent years, is from private operations. Unfortunately, capital influx data are not available in any greater detail than that presented in Table VII-2. Analyzing Capital Flows: Tyler's Linear Regre551on Equat1on To analyze the determinants of capital influx into the Brazilian balance of payments William G. Tyler has estimated the following linear regression equation:6 F - 334.19 + 9.50 i + 553.11 D (1.83) (4.23) (t values) R2 = .90 D.W. = 2.06, SSee Relatdrios 1970 and 1971 (Rio de Janeiro: Banco Central do Brasil). 6Tyler, "Exchange Rate Flexibility," p. 32. 183 .Amnma xumsunmmw hm .moflaosoom musucsnsoo pcmnaflmmnm 0U Hahucmu Oocmm .Hhmalhmma moaumumamm “mmOHDOm 0000 0000 000 000 000 00 000 00 000 00 6666066 000 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 0 A00x0000 0620 0600666 066uo-.000 00 000 00 000 06660 A0 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 060666600 666 mcmoa 00:00 mo 00 - 00 - 00 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 00 - 00 - 000 - 66660 wuouMmammEoo mo 0000- 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 6660060000666 00 00 - 00 - 00 - - - - - - - 60666666>60 10 0000- 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 000 - 63600660-.00 00 00 00 00 00 A00\0000V mUCOEUmm>chm Av 000 000 00 000 00 0660c 00 0000 0000 000 000 000 000 000 000 00 06660066 60 000 000 000 000 000 000 00 000 000 666660606 60 0000 0000 0000 0000 000 000 000 000 000 000 060666600 666 66660 00 000 000 000 00 00 00 00 00 00 06660066 60 0 0 0 0 0 00 0 0 00 6666660606 60 000 000 000 000 00 00 00 00 00 00 60666666>60 00 0000 0000 0000 0000 000 000 000 000 000 000 6360060-.0 10660 0000 0000 0000 0000 0000 0000 0000 0000 0000 0000 .66600006 000 .0000-0000 606666>oz 0660666 6666666066-.0-00> 6066a 184 where F represents private medium- and long-term capital influx, 1 equals the real rate of interest paid to holders of bills of exchange (commercial paper) and D represents a dummy variable for the minidevaluation policy. Tyler utilized annual data from 1964 to 1970. The expected signs were found, with D statistically significant at the 1 percent level and i at a little over the 10 percent level. The significance of D, however, cannot be attri- buted solely to the minidevaluation policy. The other factors mentioned above, such as the nature of the politi- cal regime and the numerous financial reforms which have rationalized Brazilian money markets, also have played their part. These cannot be distinguished in the regres- sion analysis, however. Regression Analysis of Direct Foreign Investments The flow of direct foreign investments may be separated from that of loans and financing for the purpose of analysis. The major determinants of direct private investment are the expected rate of profit and the risk associated with it. A good proxy for profit opportunities available to foreign investors is the rate of growth of the economy. A major component of risk is that related to fluctuations in the level of the foreign exchange rate. To analyze the determinants of direct foreign investments in Brazil the following ordinary least-squares regression was estimated for 10 annual observations from 1963 to 1972: 185 I = 76.799 + 5.240 9t - 10.198 f (1.921) (-2.107) t (t values) ( .096) ( .073) (significance) R2 = .825 fi2 = .774 F = 16.449 Significance .002, D.W. = 2.11, no autoregression, where I represents constant dollar value of direct foreign investments in Brazil, yt equals the real rate of growth of the country's gross domestic product, and ft the annual average of the monthly percentage variation (with no signs) in the real official exchange rate. The lower the level of ft’ the lower the level of fluctuations (and of exchange risk) in the real exchange rate (see discus- sion of this variable in Appendix E). Table G-l in Appendix G shows the data used in estimating the above regression. It can be seen that the value of ft is much lower after 1968, during the minidevaluations, than before. The regression shows high overall significance and a good fit. The coefficients of both 9t and ft show the expected signs. That of 9t is statistically signi- ficant at the 10 percent level and that of ft at the 7 percent level.' Therefore, this result indicates that the minidevaluations, by diminishing the exchange rate risk associated with the returns to foreign investors, had a positive influence on direct foreign investments.) Other factors which affect the expectations of foreign investors, such as political events, were not taken into account. The portfolio approach in the next section will consider them. 186 Analyzipg Capital Flows: The Portfolio Approach The portfolio approach to analyzing short-term capital movements also can provide insights to the recent upsurge of foreign capital in Brazil. The portfolio theory views each financier as holding a portfolio of financial assets, the composition of which is designed to maximize his return subject to minimum risk. A major determinant of the portfolio distribution between domestic and foreign assets is the constellation of interest rates prevailing in the domestic and foreign money markets. In the case of an English investor, for example, the composition of his portfolio can be represented by <‘.l< rf nr6 = 9 (ii, iii. st). (1) where Vi is the fraction of net worth, Vt' foreign securities, 1: the foreign interest rate, i: the domestic rate, and st includes variables such as evaluation of risk and exchange rate expectations. held in The equilibrium holdings of foreign assets can be represented by f_ .f .d Vt — Vt g (1t, it, St)' (2) For the English investor considering Brazilian securities, the policy of minidevaluations coupled with the 187 stability of the Brazilian government would represent an important favorable change in the variable 5, which can be represented by .61!— V0 9.3 (3) The decrease in risk would encourage the financier to include more Brazilian securities in his portfolio. Similarly, a variation in the interest rate can be represented by7 91:83fo (4) An increase in the return on Brazilian securities would cause the financier to include more of them in his portfolio. These stock shift effects are one-time changes in portfolio distribution. As the portfolio grows over time, the higher return on the foreign (Brazilian) asset should raise the fraction of portfolio growth that contributes to accumulation of foreign assets. With a given vector of interest rates, the growth in foreign (Brazilian) assets is given by 7See T. H. Branson and T. D. Willet, "Policy Toward Short-Term Capital Movements, Some Implications of the Portfolio Approach," paper presented at the Confer- ence on International Mobility and Movement of Capital sponsored by The National Bureau of Economic Research, January, 1970; Kreinin, International Economics, pp. 75-76. EE‘ = 0 = vg (i , i . s). (5) An increase in the foreign interest rate (or a decrease in the exchange rate risk) will increase vf, the equilibrium flow into foreign assets, by 917?: 6231f, 0- di 81 This is a continuing flow effect. The very general model of portfolio distribution given by Eq. (1) implies a fairly rigid relationship between the continuing flow and stock shift effects. Dividing Eq. (6) by Eq. (4), one obtains: de/di v Flow effect _ Stock effect _ t dVE/di Vt The ratio of the flow effect to the stock effect is equal to the rate of growth of the "scale variable." Thus, if the portfolio is growing at, say, 10 percent per year, then an increase in the foreign rate of 1 percent would cause a stock shift of, say, $500 thousand, and the effect on the continuing annual outflow initially would be $50 million per year. This effect itself also would grow at a 10 percent annual rate. 189 The portfolio approach indicates that the flow effect is small relative to the stock shift effect. It is changing interest rates that produce large continuing flows in the balance of payments; high rates primarily affect reserves. In the light of this theory, how could one explain the continuous capital upsurge into Brazil, especially since 1968? Table VII-3 shows the differential between the real return on two selected securities, the Brazilian bill of exchange, an almost riskless commercial paper, and the London Euro-Dollar three-month deposits. This differential has been continuously increasing since 1968. Therefore, according to the portfolio theory, this increase should result in both stock shift and flow effects, which then would produce a substantial capital influx into Brazil. Another good proxy to indicate the rentability of investments in Brazil is the rate of growth of the economy. This rate also has increased sub- stantially and almost continuously since 1968. It constitutes a sign that Brazilian assets have become increasingly interesting to foreigners in recent years. Unfortunately, the flow and stock effects cannot be separated empirically. The portfolio theory also does not say much about lags in the response of investors to changes in expected returns of different assets. In addition, the analysis of capital flows should take into account political events, such as coup-d'états, elections, 190 HMGOHfimflaHmanH .ANBmH .800000m .HBmH 00006 mm6b com 086 00380>ozv mm .60080800m 60:085h800 m .mhmH 000m¢ .mzH .000000060m 060086800 .00000006 30808-m 000 0800060050 >006p mo 00600>< N .Aman 003800090 00060m 06 0600800 0086m 0>m0 00 as 00008068 3080810 000 006 83030 00063 .000060 0600008800 00000000 000806 006 A003860 06 0600000 008630xm mo 0000m 0 m.~0 0.00 6.0 m.v w.m m.m 006m 0600oo 008m 80 808003 60060000 08808 008630xm mo 000m 80 808003 60060000 0.0- 0.0- 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 06660600 000089 80 x0p8H 00000 00880800 06 66060066 6068 060066 6066 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 06660600 660060 660 60 86660 66006 00880800 80 008630 0060800000 068880 0.00 0.0 v.0 m.m o.m 0.0 00060m 80 x0680 00000 0600800 >3 60060009 0m8630xm mo 000m 80 80800m v.00 m.00 m.m0 0.0m m.mm o.mm m00~60m 80 80880 00000 0600800 030 80 008630 006080000m 06588¢ ~.mm m.om m.om m.om m.0m m.mm 00060m 80 0008630xm 00 000m 00 006003 00 p060 80800m 0680802 N000 0>m0 onm0 mmm0 mmm0 hmm0 .0063 00000080 806800 060009 008m 060m 030 686 00060m 80 008630xm mo 000m 6 80 808003 0603 030 800300m 06008000000Q|-.m-HH> mqmds 191 nationalizations, revolutionary movements, regression, and so forth, to which they are sensitive. Thinking in terms of Eq. (1) above, these qualitative events can be represented by changes in the variable 5, which denotes evaluation of risk. The annual growth in the flow of direct private investment and in loans and financing into Brazil may be compared to the differential between the real return on a Brazilian bill of exchange and on a Euro-Dollar deposit and also with the rate of growth of Brazil's GDP. (See Table.VII-4.) The low rates of growth (proxy for invest- ment rentability) and the highly unstable political situation during 1963 and 1964 had a substantial negative impact on both direct investment and loans and financing flows. The military take-over and the government's policy favoring foreign investment caused important "stock" and "flow" effects on capital influx. Direct private invest- ment, especially, increased 150 percent in 1965. The period 1966-1968 presented moderate growth. In August 1968 the initiation of the minidevaluation policy repre- sented an important step in diminishing the risk involved in the fluctuations of the exchange rate. The year 1968 was also the beginning of a long period of high growth for the Brazilian economy. As a result, 1969 presented a 72 percent increase in a direct private investment and a 90 percent increase in loans and financing funds, an indication that substantial positive "stock" and "flow" effects occurred in that year. Since 1969 the return differential .00000 006660 020 .6600606600 00080000v 000600 00 0000800 00860 ‘8000000 .6>666 0100> 666 0100> 660660 060080800 0680006800080 “Amnm0 “Amhm0 .00080>ozv mm .000808000 600080h800 ”000000 192 0.mm0 mmmw oom m.00 Nvom 000 m.wm 0060 mm0 v.0m mmo0 0.00 mm0 0.0 m.v m.v m.v m.mm m.vw mmm 0mm mom mom o.om0 0m 00 00 on o.mm 0mm 0.01 mm m.m 111 0110300080 080080800 086 08000 80 003000 000880 000 08000008 000 110300080 080086800 086 08600 06009 111 0110300080 0808000>80 006>000 000000 80 003000 060880 om 08000008 00011000808 1000>8000 000000x0v 00808000>80 006>000 000000 00 0300080 m.0 0110000000 00000800 00000 0600 800000600 06 663600 06 6066 .11 0110066066 660066 000m 80 800000 0600 00808 008600xm 00 0000 80 800000 0600 N000 00m0 onm0 mom0 mmm0 hmm0 mwm0 mmm0 vwm0 mmm0 .0000000 00 300080 000 086 0808000 000 00 003000 00 0060 000 .0000000000 8000000 080 00000800 80 800000 06008000000011. 61100> 00048 193 between a Brazilian security and a Euro-Dollar deposit has grown continuously, and this has resulted in a continuous rise in loans and financing. The increasing high rates of growth in loans and financing from 1970 to 1972 again indicate the concomitant "stock" and "flow" effects. Direct private investments decreased a small 7.9 percent in 1970. This can be attributed to the uncertainty created by the following events: the incapacitation of President Costa e Silva in August 1969; the election of General Emilio Garrastazu Médici--until then not generally known by the people--by the Congress after his selection by the high command of the armed forces in October 1969; and the appearance, heretofore very unusual in Brazil, of a leftist terrorist movement which, in its most daring act, kidnapped the U. S. Ambassador to Brazil in September 1969. By the end of 1970 the new government was proving itself administratively successful, efficient in curbing both terrorism and other forms of political dissent, and very friendly to foreign investors. The economy was show- ing increasing rates of growth. As a result, the flow of direct private investment increased by 14.1 percent in 1971 and by 37 percent in 1972. Although many factors contributed to the exceptional increase in capital influx into Brazil after 1968, it seems clear that the minidevalua- tion policy was a key, and probably a necessary, factor. On the side of outflows (see Table VII-2), the increase in the amortizations of loans and financing, which 194 have occurred with a lag in relation to the respective inflows, is to be expected. The net inflow-outflow balance has shown an accelerated growth since 1968. The large surplus in the capital account has financed the balance in the current account and also has resulted in an unprecedented increase in foreign indebtedness and accumu- lation of foreign exchange reserves. In fact, this increasing net influx of capital may have tempted the authorities to diminish the rate of exchange depreciation. A decline in the real exchange rate, ceteris paribus, tends to make local currency, short- term debt instruments still more attractive to foreigners, thus increasing the short-term capital influx. As noted in Chapter II, the real exchange rate adjusted for 8 The dollar inflation has declined a little since 1968. following example serves to explain why rates of devalua- tion smaller than the difference between the domestic and external inflation rates might make local debt instruments more attractive to foreigners. Suppose the exchange rate at the beginning of the year is Cr$l.00 = US$1.00. In addition, suppose that: (l) the nominal interest rate paid on a riskless Brazilian Treasury Bill in Brazil is 25 percent per year, whereas it 8This decline is based on a comparison of either the wholesale price index for all commodities or the consumer (cost of living) price index in both Brazil and the United States. There is no decline when the whole- sale industrial price index in Brazil is considered. For capital flows, however, the price index for all goods, not simply for industrial goods, is more relevant. 195 is 8 percent on a riskless U.S. Treasury Bill; (2) the annual rate of inflation in Brazil is 18 percent, in the United States, 3 percent; (3) the Brazilian authorities devalue the cruzeiro several times during the year by a total of 13 percent, that is, 2 points less than the difference (15 percent) between inflation rates in the two countries; (4) there is no fee for exchange rate transac- tions or income tax on returns in both countries; and (5) the U.S. authorities do not change the official par value of the dollar. Assume now that a U.S. resident invests US$lO0.00 in Brazilian Treasury Bills and the same in U.S. Treasury Bills at the beginning of the year. At the end of the year his Brazilian Treasury Bill will be worth US$110.62 (CR$125.00 divided by CR$l.l3), whereas his U.S. Treasury Bill will be worth US$108.00, both in nominal dollar terms.9 Therefore, the investment in the Brazilian security is more attractive, and conditions for a substan- tial net capital influx into Brazil, other things being equal, are created. Had the total annual devaluation of the cruzeiro been 15 percent, the Brazilian Treasury Bill would be worth US$108.70 fCR$125 divided by CR$l.lS), and the return differential would be negligible. The advantage given to the foreign investor in the former case is really not so secure because he does not know whether the government will continue to devalue the 91n terms of constant dollar value (considering the 3 percent annual rate of inflation in the United States) at the end of the year the Brazilian Treasury Bill will be worth US$107.40 and the U.S. Treasury Bill US$104.85. 196 cruzeiro by less than the differential in inflation rates during the next year. The expectation of foreign investors, however, following the second year of experience with the minidevaluations, has been that the monetary authorities have tended to devalue the currency by little less than the difference in inflation between the Brazilian and U.S. general (for all commodities) price indexes. As a result, they may have been expecting the advantage provided by the system in loan operations, which might by an additional reason for the increase in the net influx of capital into Brazil since 1968. The Effects of Minidevaluations on Foreign Indebtedness and Accumulation of Foreign Reserves Since the initiation of the minidevaluations, important changes have occurred in foreign indebtedness and in the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves as a result of trade performance and of the movements in capital flows. As shown in Table VII-5, the external debt of Brazil, which had oscillated between US$3.0 billion and US$3.7 billion from 1960 to 1967, increased dramati- cally after 1968 and attained the level of US$lO.2 billion in December 1972. Concomitantly, the foreign exchange reserves which were at the very low level of about US$200 million in 1967, rose by an even larger rate, to US$3,952.6, in December 1972. The concept of net foreign indebtedness is obtained by subtracting foreign reserves from external 197 TABLE VII-5.--Brazi1's Foreign Indebtedness and Foreign Reserves on December 31, 1960-1972. External Debt Reserves Indebizgness (l) (2) (3) = (l - 2) Year Value Index Value Index Value Index 1960 3,071.0 100.0 345.0 100.0 2,726.0 100.0 1961 3,080.0 100.3 470.0 136.2 2,610.0 95.7 1962 3,183.1 103.7 285.0 82.6 2,898.1 106.3 1963 3,185.5 103.7 219.0 63.5 2,966.5 108.8 1964 3,101.1 101.0 245.0 71.0 2,856.1 104.8 1965 3,478.4 113.3 484.0 140.3 2,994.4 109.8 1966 3,702.4 120.6 425.0 123.2 3,277.4 120.2 1967 3,372.0 109.8 199.0 57.7 3,173.0 116.4 1968 3,917.0 127.5 257.0 74.5 3,660.0 134.3 1969 4,403.3 143.4 657.0 190.4 3,746.3 137.4 1970 5,295.2 172.4 1,187.0 344.1 4,108.2 150.7 1971 6,621.6 215.6 1,642.0 476.0 4,979.6 182.7 1972 1,170.0 331.2 3,952.6 1,145.7 6,217.4 228.1 Source: Conjuntura Economica, 26 (April 1972) and 27 (March 1973). 198 debt. Column (3) of Table VII-6 indicates that Brazil's net foreign indebtedness has almost doubled during the period of minidevaluations, from US$3.2 billion at the end of 1967 to US$6.2 billion at the end of 1972. Increases in both foreign indebtedness and foreign exchange reserves have been the result of deliberate government policy aimed at two objectives:10 First there was a desire to increase the absorption of foreign savings to supplement the domestic saving effort. This would permit higher rates of investment and, consequently, economic growth. Second, the government wishes to direct the growth in foreign indebtedness, which results from the pursuit of the first objective toward medium- and long-term feasibility. Whereas the net influx of capital has financed the deficit in the balance of goods and services, the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves - has bolstered foreign investors' confidence in the capacity of the Brazilian economy to meet its obligations and has become a reserve to be used in any short-run crisis that might eventually affect the foreign exchange earnings of the country. The minidevaluations have facilitated the implementation of the foreign indebtedness policy. 10Stated by the Director of Exchange of Banco Central do Brasil, Paulo H. Pereira Lira, in "Politica de Endividamento Externo" (unpublished conference paper delivered to the Superior War College, July 1972), and also discussed by him in an interview with this author in August 1972. 199 They have established the conditions for reasonable econ- omic calculations in foreign exchange operations, with the result that these operations have been normalized. Using computer simulation methods, monetary authorities have been able to forecast with reasonable accuracy Brazil's future foreign indebtedness behavior, its payment obliga- tions, and its capacity to pay. The authorities have been closely following the level and term structure of foreign indebtedness, and they have taken the necessary steps to prevent undesirable developments. Since 1969 they have improved the information system. All foreign exchange operations, with specified payment terms, have been required to be registered at the Central Bank. Indirect type of controls, that is, controls which do not interfere with individual contracting parties, have limited the volume of short-term borrowing to levels considered safe by the authorities. Table VII-6 shows that, despite a substantial increase, net foreign indebtedness averaged only 1.6 times the value of merchandise exports from 1969 to 1972,11 compared to an average of 1.9 from 1965 to 1968 and 2.1 from 1960 to 1964. The term structure of foreign indebtedness also has had a salutary change. Short-term (up to one year) borrowing as a proportion of total debt declined 11This means that the level of net foreign indebt- edness (foreign indebtedness less foreign exchange reserves) could be paid by the foreign exchange earnings generated by the exports of approximately one year and seven months. 200 TABLE VII-6.--Brazil's Net Indebtedness and Exports, 1960-1972, US$ millions. Net Indebtedness Exports of Merchandise (1) (2) Year Value Index Value Index 1/2 1960 2,726.0 100.0 1,270.0 100.0 2.1 1961 2,610.0 95.7 1,405.0 110.6 1.9 1962 2,898.1 106.3 1,215.0 95.7 2.4 1963 2,966.5 108.8 1,406.0 110.7 2.1 1964 2.856.1 104.8 1,430.0 112.6 2.0 1965 2,994.4 109.8 1,595.5 125.6 1.9 1966 3,277.4 120.2 1,741.4 137.1 1.9 1967 3,173.0 116.4 1,654.0 130.2 1.9 1968 3,660.0 134.3 1,881.3 148.1 1.9 1969 3,746.3 137.4 2,311.2 182.0 1.6 1970 4,108.2 150.7 2,738.9 215.7 1.5 1971 4,976.6 182.7 2,903.6 228.7 1.7 1972 6,217.4 228.1 3,990.0 314.2 1.6 Source: Conjuntura Economica, 26 (April 1972): and 77*(March 1973). 201 from 1969 to 1970, whereas medium- and long-term debt increased. Table VII-7 indicates that this trend was slightly reversed in 1971. During 1972 there was a relatively large surplus of disposable funds in the main world money markets; in addition, Brazil's political and economic outlook was considered excellent by foreign investors, especially in relation to other areas in Latin America, Africa, or Asia. This situation was reflected in the so-called "Brazil risk rate,‘ the additional rate over the London interbank offering rate, LIBO, which is normally charged by foreign investors. During 1969-1971, the Brazil risk rate was 2.5 to 3.5 percent per year over the LIBO rate (which ranged from 5 to 6 percent per year) for three- year loans; during 1972 it decreased to 1.5 percent over the LIBO rate for five-year loans.12 As a result, the foreign indebtedness of Brazil accelerated. In October 1972 the government decided to require that borrowers deposit 25 percent of the value of their foreign loans with the Central Bank. This made foreign loans more expensive to borrowers, but the net capital influx continued at a high level afterward. The authorities might have used an alternative desincentive for the foreign suppliers of funds: devaluation of the Brazilian currency by slightly 12From interviews by the author with Paulo H. Pereira Lira, Director, Banco Central do Brasil; Fernao C. Botelho Bracher, Director, Banco da Bahia; and Roberto C. de Barros Barreto, Director, Banco de Investimentos do Brasil, August 1972. o.ammwms .mmma .mcoHHHHE m.nmmmms .omma pom.mcoHHHHE "powMfloQO on ou mfiumu nuw3 mcoflumnmmo modaocw #0: 06 must one .wmsma HmHmaw om "muoz m .moHEocoom mususshcou pcm .Hflmmum 0p Hmuucmo oocmm mo mcflumaom pom moflnmumaom “moousom mél. H.mmm.¢ m.mm m.ovw.m “Umm v.nmo.m mung” 3.. 0u as m.om m.omo.v x..vm N.hmm.m N.mm H.Nm¢.m mummm m on as “Nov N.mmm.m mlvv m.vvm.m o.mv m.omm?_.. mummm m on QD N..vm m.mmm..n mlmm mimmm...” N.oN H.vm.n..m Ham» .... OH QD Hmuoa Hm>o w msam> HMDOB um>o w mjam> Hmuoe Hm>o w msam> EHmB msma .Hm umnsmoma Ohms .Hm nonsmomo mmma .Hm “mnsmoma .mGOAHHHE mm: .mmmcwmunwch cmflmuom m.HHNmum mo musuosuum EHoBII.hIHH> mamfia 203 higher rates or by the full differential between internal and external inflation. The influx of capital as well as imports probably would have diminished, whereas exports probably would have increased. Import tariffs could have been reduced if the government wanted to maintain the same level of imports that would occur at lower exchange rates. The Behavior of Services As shown in Figures VII-1, VII-2, and VII-3, from 1947 to 1972 the Brazilian balance on service items always has shown a deficit. This has been due to many reasons. First, until recently, because of the lack of an adequate shipping industry, Brazil depended almost entirely on foreign shippers. Second, unlike Mexico, Greece or Egypt-- which have ancient cultural heritages constituting major tourist attraction-—Brazi1, despite its natural beauty and surging modern civilization, has not yet been selected as one of the world's major tourist attractions. In the past 26 years, Brazilians have traveled abroad much more than foreigners have traveled to Brazil. Third, as a net borrower and as a capital-importing country, Brazil has had a continuous deficit in its capital income account. Fourth, interest, profits, and dividends have constituted major service payment items. Insurance (except since 1971), government transactions, and other services such as management fees, technical assistance, patents and royalties, film rentals, and underwriters, commissions, and agents' fees complete the list of service items which 204 Figure VII-1.--Brazil's Balance of Services, 1947-1971, Current Dollar Value. 205 am or P— mm P P P‘T U! 1") lf} (... we hvma - I 03 room I 2: I 2:. l com .... com r. 2: 1- com I. com I02: I 8: l 83 1:00: I coca Tooma mcoflssse \u ImOD mcohumnam>mmflcafi mo UOALQQ m 206 Figure VII-2.--Service Payments, 1947-1971, Current Dollar Value. 207 ‘9 H \D O u.) m Pm mm hm mm mm cm mm mm Hm om mw mv hvma - o o o ow mm we we o-N. mm m. Q m m P p p p n N n P (P p n P n b P - Hm>mu9 codumuuommpu I 02” 1.00m ummumucH .UCMHSmCH I oom I03 room 186 l.oon ... oom I.oom foooa ‘ t/fmnnmu 7.1...” ”cm miuMmOpd. .l OOHH [Ill/III, pqufloam baa .mVOAJummcwua DCCECtm>OU I coma v (flflmrkomam /!I‘ WFJUHlarHWam (HUNUO IOOMH mucoC%0d wufl>umm aspen l.o°va ocma mQOA 43 .m.: ‘1' mcosumnamnbnecfle mo noHuoa AA. .0. 208 Figure VII-3.--Service Receipts, 1947-1971, Current Dollar Value. 209 Nb mv we ncma as ch mo mm mm wm mm «0 we Ho Ho ow mm mm mm mm mm um mm mm a- on p b bl: » b p p s p b) by p n (b p p p‘ p b, p (b p (Ll - Ho>dwa l 111 (J coflumuuommcmue 1:- \f- .l OOH .\\~ ‘ I . ,\ ..oom loom //////////MWIII mum ,,m{n umw«.uc« .rn .JCvuxranmu r.oov 11!! mum» umn umnuo mumflmumm m-- “um H-u0b 1.00m mcoHHHAS . m .m.D -4 < 'n r. Oaumr, m>mmwuafi no wnfluwo 210 have contributed continuously to the deficits in the Brazilian service account. The importance of the service account to the Brazilian balance of payments can be illustrated by the following observation: Although the Brazilian balance of trade (exports minus imports in fob value) had only five deficit years between 1947 and 1972,1’3 the balance of goods and services presented deficits in 19 out of the 26 years of the same period. Each of the service items has been influenced by important government measures. Only the major changes in the service accounts during the period under which the minidevaluations were in effect will be noted here. Travel Table VII~8 shows the Brazilian balance of services for the period 1960-1971. Since 1968 travel payments have increased sharply and much more than travel receipts. In 1971 travel expenses were 375 percent higher, in current dollar value, than the annual average for 1964-1967, whereas travel receipts were 89 percent higher than the annual average for 1964-1967. This has occurred despite strict regulation of currency sales for travel purposes. Since January 1968 each Brazilian who travels abroad has been allowed to purchase a maximum of US$1,000.00 in foreign exchange. He also has been allowed to receive a 131952, 1960, 1962, 1971, 1972. 211 .mmsmmH Hmuw>wm .Hflmmum 0U Hmnucmo oocmm .Eflumaom "condom .mmmno>m Hmscc«« .mpcoewmmN .mumflmome who III mam III omw III mmm III mow III vmm III mocmamm mm mm vm mm mm mm mm mm Honuo oa m m m m m h N mommma pom mmfluammou .mucwpmm NNH mm mm «N vw ma mm Na mosmumwmmm Hmowc Inomu was unmammmcmz mma hNH mma mm ova on mNH mm VNH 5N mad mm mmofl>umm Hmnuo .w mNH Ne mod mm Nm mN mm mN on mm hv vN muon3mmam oopsaocfl uoc mGOHu Iommcmna pamEde>oo .m HNH N mad o Hm o em 0 mm o MN o mocmofl>fip pom mnemoum mvm Nv va om voN NN «ma oH mma m HHH m ummumucH vmv vv mow om mmN NN mmN oH mma m vma m mEoocH Hmuflmmu .v om vm MN oa ma m ma h Ha v NH m mUCMMSmcH .m mwN mm moN Nu HmH mm Hm NmH ma mv NN vm umzuo mma mm mma hm can as -sma ow mm as moa ma usmflmum Hmv Hma vvm mma HoN mNH mmH Nm moa mm nNH nv coaumunommcmue .N aha mm ooa om baa mN mma ha mm ma Nv ma Hm>mua .H NNvH vvv mafia mom oNo omN Hon mON «mm Hma How nNH Hmuoa m m m m m m m m m m Nm Hm Huma ohma mmma mood «nm\vmma «mm\omma .mcoaaaaa mmo .Hnmauomma .mmoa>umm no moamamm m.aflumumuu.muHH> mqm02 .moaeozoom musucmflcou "condom H no.0 N.o v.oH mm.mH vN.NH oo.Hm m.NH Nan H Nm.o m.o m.HH mm.ON mo.mH mm.om >.mH Han H nN.H v.o m.m HH.0N mn.NH vH.mN m.HN oan H Nm.H w.o o.m VN.mH nm.mH ov.Nm m.oN mme H vm.m N.H m.m mo.HN Ho.mN HN.Nv N.VN mme H mm.N n.H m.v Hm.mN mm.mH mo.mm v.mN nmmH o nv.N H.H H.m mw.om mN.5H oH.nm m.nm ommH o «N.m w.H n.N vo.Hm ov.mm mm.mm m.wm momH o Nv.n N.m m.N mm.mm oo.o0H Hm.wm m.om vmoH o vH.v N.v m.H om.mm mv.mm HN.mm v.mn mmmH o mm.v m.v m.m VN.Hm Hh.mm ov.mm w.Hm NomH o mm.v v.m m.OH wH.mm mm.HN oo.oN o.nm HmmH o mm.m m.N n.m oo.oH No.m om.mw N.mN ommH o mN.m o.N w.m wv.mm MH.mm NH.>N m.nm mmmH o vm.m H.N w.~ oo.o om.om «H.mm o.MH mmmH o nm.v v.m H.m nv.mN Nm.NNI mn.MN N.vH nmmH o no.HH v.N N.m NN.mN mm.MH mo.ON m.mH mmmH o Hm.w m.o m.m mH.Nm Ho.mm mo.mH v.oH mmmH o m.HH m.o H.OH NN.wv mv.mv mv.HN o.nN vmmH mN.mH m.vH mmmH om.NH m.HH NmmH noboom .munomEH gnu Lo Adamo “mausoe NH Amaucoe NH Amnucoe NH Ammo» mcu new» HmHuumsch on» MOW mums :oHuuomoud mfiooca mo mmmuw>mv mo mmmum>mv mo mmmum>mv mo wowum>mv CH mHouucoo omcmxoxw m we Hmmm momz mum» memsm xoUcH ooHuQ wo Hmmm ocu uHuame EsfiHcHz omcmnoxw xmcoz moaum ucmEmou0wcw MON CH wucmno snowmoue quQEH Hmuwcmo mHomHum> NEEDQ ommucmoumm HmcoHuwz HmHonmo NHnucou who wo womnw>d CH coHumHue> momucwoumm Hmsccd .HHNmnm 2H uoH>mcom ooHum chHaxm Cu mHmpoz cH coma moHanum> wo mosHm>nl.NnHHH> mqmummno ummmq Numchuo Hmscc< mH “oHQMHum> ucmocommo who mm no cqu mGOHmmmuoom mmumsvm .mcoHumonwpoz cyw3 Hmooz Homnmhmm on» NO coHDMOHHmmd .Hsumum cH noH>mamm mosum co mcoflpmsam>meflaflz may no powwow was mo ummeuu.suHHH> mamas 234 mumvmmsH .sonmmumoHODsw mo mocmmmum may ou mm m>HmoHosoocw m> UHumHumum QOmumxchnusn one .NHw>HuommmmH .mucmHOHmwmoo pmumfiwumm may mo mHm>mH oUCMOHMHcon onu can mmon>Iu on» cam psoHonmmoo some Hops: .HuHHH> magma cw cm>flm mum mmanmflum> 6:» mo maofiuflcflmme was mononucmumm CH mnmnasc one mooo.ov on.hN mom. mmm. AoHo. V Hoom.N V vho.¢ mooo.ov MBH.N5 mom. who. Aasm. V AmmH.H V mom.H mooo.ov mom.om mom. omm. “Nov. AMHh. I 5mm.N Ammo. AmHv. mum. mw.H mv.H mh.H mooo.ov mooo.ov mooo.ov mmw.hm mob.MHH wow.mH vmm. Nmm. mmm. who. omm. mow. V V V V ve.a .z.o mooo.ov .mHm mam.mm m mam mm mam mm U0 56 a. nu 235 Also, the significance of all other individual coeffi- cients is substantially increased. The coefficient of ft in Equation (9), in particular, more than doubles (in absolute value) with respect to its value in Equation (7) and is significant at the 19 percent level. Its negative sign indicates again that minidevaluations have not been an inflationary factor. The fourth model considered is a modified version of Harberger's basic approach. Additional policy variables were considered as follows: * * I3t = 80 + Blmt + Bzyt + B3‘1"; + B4at + B5ft + B6ét + B7dt + Bact . 0* O O * pt = 80 + B1mt + B3Y1: + B3wt + 84% + B5ft + B6ét + 87dt Equations (10) and (11) in Table VIII-4 are the regression results of estimating these models. The coefficient of determination corrected for the number of degrees of freedom, §2' is almost the same in both Equations (10) and (11) as that obtained in Equation (9) with a smaller number of variables. The coefficients of e the added policy variables, d and c show the t' t' t expected signs but are insignificant. It is interesting to note, however, that the coefficient of the 236 minidevaluation variable, f substantially increases (in t' absolute value) with respect to the corresponding one in Equation (9). It is negative, and it becomes significant at the 8 and 7 percent levels, respectively, in Equations (10) and (11). This result implies that minidevaluations have helped the government in curbing inflation. Equation (12) is similar to (11), except for the deletion of the expectation variable a:. Here the coefficients of the variables ét’ the percentage change in the real exchange rate for imports, and dt’ the National Treasury deficit as a proportion of Gross Domestic Pro- duct, become significant, respectively, at the 6 and 2 percent levels. The coefficient of the minidevaluation variable, ft' has about the same value as in Equation (10), but its significance drops to the 14 percent level. Conclusion The results presented in this section indicate that the policy of minidevaluations have not constituted an inflationary factor, and that, on the contrary, may have aided the government in its pursuit of gradual stabiliza- tion of prices in Brazil. 237 The Effects of Minidevaluations on Economic Growth After obtaining increasingly high rates of growth during the postwar years, averaging 6.4 percent between 1948 and 1956 and 8.3 percent during 1957-1961, the Brazilian economy presented a poor growth performance from 1962 to 1967. The average annual increase in real product was only 3.7 percent in this period, quite low in comparison with the annual population growth rate of 2.89 percent during the sixties. From 1968 through 1972, however, the period during which the minidevaluations were in effect, Brazil's economic growth was the highest in the country's history. During these four years, the real Gross Domestic Product grew at an annual average of 9.9 percent and in 1971 and 1972 it reached 11.3 and 10.4 percent, respectively, among the highest in the world. This section presents the results of econometric tests of the possible influence on this growth performance of minidevaluations, which might have helped the economy in attaining greater efficiency and higher rates of growth for several reasons.10 First, since divergences in cost and price trends between the domestic and foreign markets have been largely eliminated, the pull and fall in imports and exports that 10See Donges, Brazil's Trotting_Peg. 238 otherwise would occur due to internal inflation have been avoided. The miniadjustments in the exchange rate have constituted an important instrument in making a gradual stabilization policy feasible, as opposed to a shock treatment policy to counteract difficulties in the balance of payments. As a result, disturbances which cause production losses have been avoided, and chances for a steadier and faster growth rate have increased. Second, the substantial decrease in the exchange rate risk due to minidevaluations has reduced the incentives for firms which produce, sell, or buy export- ables and importables to speculate with their stocks of merchandise. Under the old system of sharp changes in the exchange rate separated by long intervals, importers would try to buy large amounts of imported goods whenever they felt a sharp devaluation was going to occur. Con- comitantly, sales of goods competing with imports would decline sharply. The reverse would occur just after the sharp devaluations. Exporters, on the other hand, during inflationary and pegged exchange rate periods, would pile up goods, await a new devaluation, and then sell merchandise for the maximum cruzeiro sales revenue. The decrease in such speculative stock fluctuations also has allowed for greater efficiency and steadier rates of growth. In addition, the removal of the exchange rate risk has facilitated investment planning for all firms 239 directly or indirectly involved with foreign exchange Operations. Two very simple growth models and two slightly more sophisticated ones were applied to test the effects of minidevaluations on growth. Unavailability of appro- priate data, however, has all but prevented the study from obtaining very meaningful results in the applica- tion of the more SOphisticated growth models. A Simple Growth Model The equilibrium condition of a simple macroeconomic model which assumes fixed prices and no government requires that the total income (output), Y, equal the total expenditure, E, where Y = C + S, E C + I + X - M, and C = consumption, S = saving, I = investment, X exports of goods and services, and M = imports of goods and services. Both X and M do not include payments of services for the use of foreign capital received in previous periods in the form of interest, profits, and dividends. 240 In equilibrium, Y = C + I + X - M, or I=(Y-C)+(M-X), where Y - C = Sd = domestic saving, and M - X = Se = foreign saving, Rewriting the equilibrium condition, I=S+S (I) At any time t, the conditions for long-run equili- brium on the product market also require that the capital stock K be utilized at full capacity. This may be 11 expressed as K = vY for all t, or Y=CXKI where a i = output-capital ratio. llSee R. G. D. Allen, Macro-Economic Theory, A Mathematical Treatment (New York: MacMillan and st. Martin's Press, 1968), chapter 10. 241 The relation between the change in output and change in capital stock may be written as dY = adK (II) but, by definition, I = dK. Then, from expressions (I) and (II), dY = c.(Sd + Se). Dividing by Y, This expression indicates that the rate of growth in real output is a function of the output-capital ratio and of the sum of the domestic saving rate and the foreign saving rate. In an alternative notation, it may be written yt = a (st + bt), (III) where annual rate of growth in Gross Domestic ‘< rt. ll Product (GDP), t domestic saving as a proportion of GDP, and bt = deficit in the balance of goods and non-' monetary services as a proportion of GDP (M - X). 242 Growth Model (III) has been used by officials to rationalize the foreign indebtedness and growth policies pursued by the government.12 Thus, the increases obtained in both the domestic saving rate and foreign saving rate in the years 1968-1971, which have resulted in very high growth rates, constituted the accomplishment of a con- scious policy.l3 Taking a as a parameter to be estimated, Model (III) can be tested. But since the objective of the study was to test the effects of the minidevaluations, the variable ft’ the annual average rate of change in the real official exchange rate (the same that was used in the inflation models), was added to the model to obtain14 yt = 8 (st + bt) + 8ft. (IV) In Model (IV) ft enters as a qualitative variable. Because of the reasons discussed above, the smaller the fluctuations in the real exchange rate, the 2 . . . . . 1 See Lira, "Politica de End1v1damento," Appendix. 13The domestic and foreign saving rates for 1970 and 1971 used in this chapter are unpublished preliminary estimates cited in Carlos Von Doellinger, "Capitais Externos, Balanco de Pagamentos e Crescimento Econ6mico,“ Internal Document, IPEA, Ministry of Planning. 14A similar model using a dummy variable, D, to represent the minidevaluations in the place of f , where D took the value of zero before 1968, 0.34 in 1968, and 1 from 1969 to 1971 was tested and yielded results some- what less significant than those obtained in estimating Model (IV). 243 greater the rate of economic growth should be (see Appendix E). The Increase in the Labor Force as a Variable An alternative simple growth model starts from a general aggregate production function in which output is 15 a function of capital and labor: 9 = F(K,L), d)z=§-I’:-d.1<+8F 8K SE'dL° Dividing by Y, and multiplying the second term in the right hand side by % £=£s.£5& y a a 8L Y L or, in terms of coefficients to be estimated, 1 Y 2 where the investment rate 9%»= st + bt’ in equilibrium conditions,16 and it = annual percentage change in the labor force. Adding a constant term and the variable ft to denote the effects of minidevaluations, the following model is obtained: 15See Sherman Robinson, "Sources of Growth in Less Developed Countries," Quarterly Journal of Economics 85, no. 3 (August 19711 391-408. " 16In terms of ex-post data, the investment rate (gross investment over GDP) is also equal to the sum of domestic and foreign savings (with negligible differences) in the Brazilian national accounts. 244 it = 80 + 81 (st + bt) + 82 1t + 83 ft (V) Allowing for improvement in the quality of the labor force, an additional term may be added:17 yt = 80 + 81 (st + bt) + 82 1 + 8 (VI) t ét + 83 f 3 t where ét is a proxy for the annual percentage increase in the number of students that complete their education at a certain level and join the labor force. (See the discussion of this variable in estimation problems below.) Following Sherman Robinson's procedure, the growth model also can take into account the rate of factor transfers from the "backward" or agricultural sector to the "advanced" or urban sector of the economy. The rate of transfer of labor can be estimated by pt, the average annual absolute change in the percentage share of the population living in the cities. The rate of transfer of capital is measured indirectly. Assuming that the capital- output ratios are the same in the two sectors, the change in the share of the advanced sector in total output measures the rate of capital transfer. The variable at ZExcept for the inclusion of ft and the exclu- sion of interaction terms, a similar model is developed by Carlos Geraldo Langoni, "As Fontes de Crescimento Economico Brasileiro," Estudos Economicos, 2, no. 4 (1972), 3-34. The intefaction terms also are excluded by Langoni in empirical applications. See also Marcelo Selowski, "On the Measurement of Education's Contribution to Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 83 (August 1969), 449-63. 245 is the average annual absolute change in the share of the agricultural sector in Gross Domestic Product. (A negative change in a means a positive transfer of capital from 8 t agriculture to the advanced sector of the economy.)1 The growth model then may be written as Yt = 80 + 81 (St + bt) + 82 1t + 83 8t + 84 at + 85 pt + 86 ft’ (VII) where the growth rate of real product is positively related to (st + bt), lt' ét' and pt and is negatively related to at and ft' Estimation Problems and Regression Results The use of the above growth models in time series regression analysis is confronted with some data limita- tions. First, the only available information on the size of the labor force derives from the censuses taken each ten years. Therefore, it is only known that the labor force grew at 2.9 percent per year during the fifties and at 2.7 percent during the sixties. As a result, meaning- ful results cannot be obtained for the coefficient 18See Robinson, "Sources of Growth." In his cross- section study, Robinson uses (st + bt) and ('bt) as two separate variables, the first as the ratio of gross invest- ment to GNP and the second as the ratio of net foreign balances (balance on current account) to GNP. The regres- sion results of Robinson's model applied to 12 annual observations from 1960 to 1971 yielded very insignificant results, which may be due partly to data limitations. 246 of 1 Second, it is difficult to have a good measure for t' the improvement in the quality of the labor force. An accurate indicator should take into account the number of persons of different degrees of education (such as, primary, secondary, secondary technical, university) that join the labor force each year. On-the-job training also should be considered. But complete time series information for a long period was not available for these items. As a proxy for the rate of change in the number of students that complete secondary education and also as an indicator of the change in the capacity of society to absorb tech- nological progress, the variable e the annual percentage t! increase in the number of students enrolled in higher education,was used. Third, estimates of the annual absolute change in the share of population living in urban areas were available only from 1960 to 1971 and were based on the censuses of two years, 1960 and 1970. The coefficient r. 1 -.1.‘.-_ .-.1 of the year-to-year variations, pt, therefore, is not' very meaningful. There were no difficulties in finding data on s b t’ t’ at, and ft' Table VIII-5 presents the definitions of all variables, their sample means, and their simple correla- tion coefficient with the dependent variable 9t, Table VIII-6 offers the data used in the estimation, and Table VIII-7 indicates the regression results for twelve annual observations from 1960 to 1971. 247 TABLE VIII-5.--Variables Used in Growth Models, Definitions, Sample Means, and Simple Correlation Coeffi- cients: 12 Annual Observations: 1960-1971. Simple Correlation Coefficient Between the Variable Sample Variable and 9t Mean Definition 9t 1.00 6.78 Annual percentage change in real Gross Domestic Product. st - .20 16.89 Ratio of domestic savings to Gross Domestic Product. bt .64 ’l.14 Ratio of foreign savings to Gross Domestic Product. st + bt .27 18.03 Ratio of total savings (equal to gross investment in the national accounts) to Gross Domestic Product. it .27 2.72 Annual percentage increase in the labor force. ét .23 15.68 Annual percentage change in the number of students enrolled in higher educa- tion (serve as proxy both for the percentage increase in number of students who have finished intermediate education and for the increase in the capacity of the economy to absorb technological change). at - .19 - .78 Annual absolute change in the share of agricultural sector in GDP. pt - .27 1.08 Annual absolute change in share of population living in the cities. ft - .53 3.31 Annual average of the monthly percentage change in the monthly real offi- cial exchange rate. It denotes the level of fluc- tuations in the real exchange rate. 214E} Nm.o Na. .m xaocoand can an you mass 88 an on- NN.H mo. .sl-m .lasas goumz-mtmncuaV mm .ONUcuopmm no nopnuwco me once OmOUumo Omeu one uneven: mu>q oth Nm.H mm. u vn.n hm.N Ho.H mo.H I HF.H 1 mm. h.on N.mH v.hH N.mH u uOu aunt one .muHumHueumM up musvHHmaum numH>0d . mom Hausa 0 acumen owueuoaom mo moueCHEHHmua me>uuoEHumuu .mo©EHm u>HHm no mo onaH can ommH mo momcmu HccoHumc mnu hv.N vN.n No.5 vH.v mo.¢ mm.v MH.H wH.H «H.H nN.H hH.H vm.~ : hh.H on. 1 oo. 1 o .oHooHocouvz 6902 cu: uoa ommH.oon co co comma ohm mouessumo .um uOu .wIM OHQMH .uchcmHm uo Nannie“: .4man xn mouussumm thcaeaHmua omnmamnsocs cum HnoH Ou .HNnoH noncw>on um .uuHewcoUm ouaucamoou .uo can .13 ..m .uH .um non "moonsom mm m an auuooea uOu uuau voodzuxo HaHuwuuo HOOH ecu cw coHuoHuu> NHnu:OI on» «o omuuu>a qund4 oN.H um wound sinus cw mcH>HH cadueHoaon we chose cu oucanu uusHOunn Huscdd 0 new as nouoou HouduHsowuou uo ounce CH mmcdcu ouoHound Ho::d< o.m 0.. am noduoosvo “ozone as vosaouco queue (sum «0 Hones: Hnuou :H moundno owflucwouoa ancd< ~.m~ ..ms an + u- mau cu “noquuco>:H ca moocozu ocwvsHooH ucwfiumv>cH amouo HnsvoV nonw>an Hauou uo oHuqu u v.0 I O.H o.N H.H H.N n moo ou mocH>om caucuOu n.6H um unsa>mm oaummEOp u n.N ~.N n.N 5.N h.N ~.N h.N n.N n.N n.N n.N m.N H mono“ so alums moo ou Lo oauum nonoH ca oo:onu.omauc00umm Hnscc< m.o~ s.m 6% moo Huou :« omcoco wumucoouom Hmocnd Han onoH momH mme nmmH oon mme vme mwaH NmmH Hon ome .ncoHumsHm>upHcat as» no accuuu on» amok cu mepoz nuJOuo no coHquHumm cH coma oueocu.o)HHH> mqmdk 249 TABLE VIII-7.-—Test of the Effect of the Minidevaluations on the Brazilian Economic Growth. Ordinary Least Squares Regressions with yt as the Dependent Variable; 12 Annual Observations: 1960-1971. Equation 1 Equation 2 Equation 3 Equation Constant —- -44.47 -78.55 -77.49 st + bt .57 .62 .80 .97 ( 5.80) ( 1.30) ( 1.62) ( 1.95) (<0.0005) ( .23) ( .15) ( .11) it 16.09 26.15 13.85 ( 1.06) ( 1.53) ( .69) ( .32) ( .17) ( .52) ét .17 .44 ( 1.17) ( 1.83) ( .28) ( .13) a 1.21 t ( 1.36) ( .23) Pt 27.58 ( 1.21) ( .28) ft - 1.07 - 1.09 ~ .82 - 2.05 (- 2.25) (- 2.29) (- 1.58) (- 2.03) ( .04) ( .05) ( .16) ( .09) R2 .40 .48 .56 .69 82 .34 .28 .31 .33 F -- 2.44 2.26 1.92 Sig. -- .14 .16 .24 D.W. 1.44 1.93 1.90 -- The definitions of the variables are given in Table VIII-5. The numbers in parentheses under each coefficient are the t-values and the significance levels of the estimated coefficients, respectively. The Durbin-WatsOn statistic values do not indicate the presence of autoregression. 250 Equation (1) in Table VIII-7 corresponds to the model (IV), the simplest. It shows a low coefficient of determination, R2 = .40. The coefficient of determination corrected for degrees of freedom, although low, R2 = .34, is the highest of the four tested models. The coefficient of (st + bt) shows the expected sign and is highly signi- ficant. The negative sign on the coefficient of ft and its significance at the 4 percent level indicate that mini- devaluations had a positive impact on the growth rate of the economy. In Equation (2), which corresponds to model (V), the coefficients of (s have the correct signs t t but are not significant. That of ft’ however, shows the + bt) and 1 same sign and about the same value as in Equation (1) and is significant at the 5 percent value. The positive effect of minidevaluations is then confirmed. In Equation (3) the inclusion of et as an explana- 2 to increase with tory variable causes the value of R respect to that of Equation (2), although not with that of Equation (1). All coefficients have the expected signs, but none is significant at the 5 percent level. Equation (4) corresponds to model (IV). It has the highest coefficient of determination, R2 = .69, but when corrected for degrees of freedom (H2 = .33) it becomes 2 slightly lower than that obtained by Equation (1) (R = .34). The coefficient of at unexpectedly shows 251 a positive sign, but it is insignificant. The coefficients of the other explanatory variables show the expected signs, but only that of ft is significant at less than the 10 percent level. The positive effect of the minidevaluations is again confirmed, although the result must be qualified in view of the low overall significance of this equation. Evidence of Greater Efficiency After Minidevaluations An examination of the residual factor in economic growth can indicate the higher efficiency of the Brazilian economy after the minidevaluations. The productivity residual is the growth of output that cannot be accounted for by the growth of labor and capital. It is shown in Appendix H that the average residual for the years 1962 to 1967 was only 0.80 percent as compared to about 5.0 percent for the years 1968 to 1972, a dramatic change. Therefore, it may be asserted that the economy became substantially more efficient after the introduction of minidevaluations. Conclusion Measurement problems have limited the application of time series regression analysis. However, the results have shown that the system of minidevaluations of the exchange rate has had a positive impact on the growth performance of the economy. Examination of the residual factor in the growth of the economy have indicated that much greater efficiency was obtained after the initiation of minidevaluations. CHAPTER IX CONCLUSION The main findings of this study were the following: The system of minidevaluations of the exchange rate at short intervals proved to have several advantages over the system of sharp devaluations at long intervals for the Brazilian economy. The main advantage was the greater stability in the relation between internal and external prices for those involved in the foreign sector of the economy. Thus, the exchange rate risk involved in export, import, direct foreign investments, and international loan operations was practically eliminated. It was shown that Brazilian exports were posi- tively affected by the policy of minidevaluations. The regression analysis showed that this policy made exports of manufactures more responsive to changes in the level of real income and significantly more responsive to changes in the level of real remuneration to exporters. This latter occurred both through changes in the real exchange rate and changes in the level of fiscal incen- tives. Exports of primary products also were shown to be 252 253 positively affected by the smaller fluctuations in the real exchange rate under the minidevaluations. The econometric analysis of imports indicated that a significant shift in the parameters of the import func- tion took place as a result of two causes: the lowering of import tariffs and the policy of minidevaluations. Imports became more responsive to income changes and especially responsive to changes in the real exchange rate adjusted for dollar inflation, tariffs, auction fees, and other trade barriers. Minidevaluations have had two major impacts on capital movements. First, they substantially diminished destabilizing short-term capital movements which previously had been harmful to the value of the cruzeiro. Second, along with other measures, they constituted a necessary condition for the exceptional influx of foreign capital into Brazil that has occurred since 1968. The regression analysis of direct foreign investments indicated that they were responsive to profit opportunities--which were represented by the rate of growth of the economy--and to the decrease in the exchange rate risk caused by the minidevaluations. It was seen that the differential between domestic and foreign levels of real interest rates played an important role in attracting foreign loans and financing into Brazil. The portfolio approach to analyz- ing capital flows showed that interest differentials and 254 the evaluation of risk, as determined by the exchange rate policy, political factors, and other events, were all important in determining the influx of foreign capital. By normalizing the expectations of economic units and by establishing the conditions for reasonable economic calculations in foreign exchange Operations, minidevalua- tions have helped the government in forecasting and managing future developments with respect to the foreign indebtedness and reserve position of the country. Under minidevaluations, the exceptional growth in exports, imports, and capital flows was accompanied by a similar increase in service payments and receipts. Among service payments the items which registered larger increases were capital income (interest, profits, and dividends), trans- portation, and travel. Among service receipts, transpor- tation and capital income increased most. The econometric analysis of price behavior indi- cated that minidevaluations have not constituted an inflationary factor. On the contrary, they may have aided the government in its pursuit of gradual stabilization of prices in Brazil. Finally, evidence was presented that minidevalua- tions had a positive impact on the growth performance of the economy. The growth of the Brazilian economy, how- ever, must be qualified. Although this dissertation has not dealt with the subjects of income distribution and 255 the political and economic regime, these dimensions must be considered in the larger context of general development strategy. According to a number of indications, during the last decade economic growth has not resulted in a general- ized improvement in welfare for a large segment of the Brazilian population. In fact, a comparative examination of Brazil's census reports for 1960 and 1970 reveals that the prevailing economic system yielded excellent results during the decade for the wealthiest 20 percent of the population, extraordinary benefits for the top 5 percent, and only some improvement for the bottom 40 percent. Whereas the richest 10 percent increased their participa- tion in total income from 39 percent in 1960 to 48 percent in 1970, the poorest 40 percent decreased their share from 11.5 percent to 10 percent.1 At the same time, Brazilian economic growth has not been accompanied by advances in political democracy. Since 1964 the Brazilian political regime has been charac— terized by repression of students, intellectuals, and labor activities; by press censorship; by no direct lSee Carlos Geraldo Langoni, "Distribuicao da Renda e Desenvolvimento EconOmico do Brasil," Estudos EconOmicos, 2 (October 1972), Table 4, p. 14; Rodolfo Hoffman and Joao Carlos Duarte, "A Distribuicao de Renda no Brasil," Revista de Administracao de Empresas, 12 (April/June 1972); and Albert Fishlow, "Brazilian Size Distribution of Income," American Economic Review, 62 (May 1972). 256 elections for major executive officials; and by prisons and torture of prisoners suspected of insurrectionist activities. These also seem to be the characteristics of other less developed countries which are experiencing high rates of growth of gross domestic product under a mixed capitalist system, and which are very receptive to multinational corporations. Greece, Iran, Turkey, and Thailand are examples. Perhaps in a few years or decades, Brazilians may decide, hopefully through the democratic process, to follow a new type of economic system which does not lead to increasing social inequities. Major decisions will have to be made with respect to both the domestic and the foreign sector of the economy. This author hopes that this study will contribute to the understanding of the role of the foreign exchange adjustment mechanism in an economy which then will be subject not only to inflationary but also to many other kinds of pressures. Some suggestions for further research new will be made. It would be interesting to estimate a "domestic resource cost" of Brazilian exports.2 If the export price 2See Hollis B. Chenery, "Comparative Advantage and Development Policy," American Economic Review, 51 (March 1961), 18-51; Edmar Bacha and Lance Taylor, "Foreign Exchange Shadow Prices: A Critical Review of Current Theories," QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 85 (May 1971), 197-224; and Michael Bruno,uWDomestIc Resource Costs and Effective Protection," Journal of Political Econom , 80 (January/February 1972), 16-33. 257 (for manufactures) can be as much as two-thirds of the domestic price owing to tax relief, credit subsidies, and the like, the domestic resource cost ratio of eXports may be considerably in excess of one. Thus one important question to examine is whether or not the "equilibrium" exchange rate which the official rate is approximating through minidevaluations is not a distorted one (or at least one which is dependent upon a highly distorted internal price structure). Another interesting point to be empirically examined is that raised by Ruben D. Almonacid about the possible negative effects of devaluation on the output of the economy through its effects on the aggregate supply of the economy. Almonacid shows that the effects of a devaluation on the aggregate supply is such that it might more than offset the expansionary effects of the devalua- tion on the aggregate demand of the economy. He argues that the slight overvaluation of the cruzeiro with respect to the dollar (taking consumer price indexes as the basis for comparison) from 1968 to 1971 has been a positive factor in stimulating the Brazilian economy.3 If this is true, it would be interesting to search for the optimum degree of overvaluation. 3Ruben Dario Almonacid, "O Efeito da Taxa Cambial Sabre o Produto," Estudos Econdmicos, 2 (October 1972), 155-70. APPENDIX A THE BATTERY OF INCENTIVES FOR EXPORTATION 258 THE BATTERY OF INCENTIVES FOR EXPORTATION Current incentives for exportation apply in general to manufactured products, but some also apply to primary goods. Table A-1 summarizes the array of incentives which constitute the prevailing international policy matrix of Brazil.1 The Fiscal Incentives Fiscal incentives in Brazil include exemptions from tarrifs, sales taxes, and income taxes on inputs, export products, and export profits.2 There also are subsidies in the form of tax credits. IPI Incentives The IPI (see footnote 5, Chapter III) or tax on industrial products, is a federal tax on the total value of production, but it effectively constitutes a tax on value added. It grew out of the old consumption tax (Imposto de Consumo) and was introduced in late 1964. Administration of the value-added aspect of the tax permits producers of final and/or exported products to deduct amounts equal to 1See Antonio Nilson Quezado Calvacanti and Ettiene Cracco, "Os incentives as exportacOes de manufaturados; analise e sugestao," Revista de Administracao de Empresas, 12, No. l (Jan./Mar. 1972), 63-69. 2The ensuing section is based on the work of William G. Tyler, Helmut Hesse, Carlos Von Doellinger, et al., and Bergsman, Brazil. 259 260 TABLE A-l.-—The International Trade Policies of Brazil. The main tools involved in planning the foreign trade sector with a view to achieving better integration of Brazil's economy in the expanding world economy. (A) Adoption of an exchange rate system involving adjust- ments at short intervals: the minidevaluations (B) Systematic effort to expand exports through (1) Fiscal Incentives: (a) (b) (C) (d) (e) (f) (g) (h) (i) (j) IPI (tax on industrial products) exemption and tax credit ICM (tax on circulation of goods) exemption income tax exemption deduction of export-promoting expenses reduction of tax on financial transfer to other countries exemption of tax on financial Operations exemption of tax on combustibles, lubricants and electric energy exemption of taxes, fees and governmental charges on goods going through Brazilian port facilities drawback tax-free import of capital goods (2) Financial Incentives: (a) (b) (C) (d) pre-export financing at low interest rates through Bank of Brazil, National Economic DevelOpment Bank, BNDE, and private commer- cial banks post-export financing at low interest rates through the same agencies listed above other credit incentives such as financing of export on consignment, of marketing operations abroad, and of economic and engineering studies of potential exports credit insurance to exporters (3) Creation of institutions to coordinate policies and promote trade 261 TABLE A-l.--Continued. (C) (d) (E) (F) (G) (4) Other Measures (a) simplification of bureaucratic procedures (b) promotional activities by Bank of Brazil, CACEX, Ministry of Foreign Relations, and other governmental and private agencies (c) remittance of samples with no formalities (d) no formalities for exports in frontier zones (e) development of export corridors (f) law regulating creation of trading companies (g) expositions Rationalization of Brazil's import policy, in part through unilateral and across-the-board tarrif reduc- tions Encouragement to foreign capital inflow and cooperation with foreign aid Introduction of a foreign indebtedness policy to provide adequate financing with which to cover the real resources gap and amortization of the existing foreign debt Policy to orient and stimulate the absorption of foreign technology Since 1964, a tough military political regime enthusiastically supported by the multinational-- mainly U.S., Western European, Japanese, Canadian, and Brazilian--business community. This regime has ensured political stability, has curbed all signs of social unrest and of potential challenges to itself, has practically forbidden labor strikes, has maintained a strict control on wages and a somewhat milder one on prices, and has multiplied the incentives for entrepreneurs to invest, make profits, and accumulate capital. 262 the sum of IPI taxes paid on input (calculated by applying the tax rate to product value) from their total tax liability. The IPI, which applies only to manufactured goods, varies from product to product. Excluding tobacco products, the average tax rate has been calculated to be 12.34 percent. There are three IPI related tax incentives for industrial exports. First, the eXporter is exempted from IPI payments which he otherwise would have to make on export products (Law No. 4,502, 30 November 1964, imple- mented in late August 1965). Second, the exporter receives a credit equal to the value of IPI taxes paid on inputs used in manufacturing the export product which may be applied against other tax liabilities.3 3Although the incidence of the IPI is on the total value of production, a provision of credits and debits eliminates its cumulative aspects, which characterized the previous consumption tax. Assume, for the sake of simpli- city, a uniform tax rate of 10 percent on the value of production instead of a 12.34 percent average. Then, assume three different firms producing goods in a chain of production. Firm A produces goods purchased and transformed by Firm B; Firm B sells the transformed goods to Firm C, which sells to Firm D after some transformation. Firm D produces the finished goods. The fiscal aspects of the entire production and sales process are shown below: Value Tax Account Value of Sales Added Production Incl. Incl. Credits Debits Balance Firm Purchases Before Tax Tax Tax A --- 100 110 110 --- ~-- - 10 B 110 300 330 220 10 30 - 20 C 330 700 770 440 30 7O - 40 D 770 1000 1100 330 70 100 - 30 263 Third, the exporter receives an additional tax credit, the value of which is related to the IPI rate applicable to the respective export product. Whereas the first two incentives are tax rebates, this credit con- stitutes a genuine subsidy. Initially, under Law No. 5.444, 30 May 1968, implemented in July 1968, the credit was conceded at a percentage equal to half the applicable IPI percentage up to a maximum of 10 percent; more recently (under Decree Law No. 491, 5 March 1969, implemented July 1969) the size of the credit was raised to 100 percent of the applicable IPI rate up to a maximum of 15 percent. These credits are redeemable against other tax liabilities due on domestic sales. For example, if a firm exports Each firm receives tax credits for all of the IPI paid in preceding stages of production. Firm B, for example, buys the product of Firm A and in this operation it receives a tax credit of 10 which was paid by Firm A. When Firm B sells its product to Firm C, a 10 percent tax on its value of production is debited to Firm B's account. Thirty is the tax debited to Firm B, so that it must pay a negative balance of 20 to the government. In effect, the tax balance is a value-added tax of 9.0909 percent of total value added, including tax, in the example. Excluding tax, the tax rate is 10 percent of net value added. Assume now that Firm D exports its finished product. Since its eXports are exempt from the IPI, it does not debit the 100 to its tax account which it would pay if the product were sold in the domestic market. But the firm still has a tax credit of 70 correspondent to taxes paid on previous stages of production. Therefore, in the above example, although the nominal tax rate on value of produc- tion is 10 percent, the effective tax rate reduction due to export is 17 percent of the value of production. Firm D benefits from the exemption of taxes paid on all previous stages of production. The supplying firms do not get this windfall, although their sales are augmented by the increased demand due to the tax exemption. 264 100 units of a certain manufactured good, it not only is exempt from the IPI that it would pay if the product were marketed domestically (plus the IPI on prior stages of production) but also is given an exemption from the IPI that it would pay on another 100 units sold in the domestic market. If the firm exports more than 50 percent of its production, the additional tax credit, or rebate, is to be deducted from other federal taxes payable.4 The IPI tax credits are applied against a fob cruzeiro value except when goods are transported and/or insured by a Brazilian company. In this case the IPI credit is based on cif value. ICM Incentives The ICM (see footnote 5, Chapter III), or goods circulation tax, is a value-added tax administered by state governments. It grew out of the old sales tax, or IVC (see footnote 5, Chapter III), which was a tax on total 4Some firms which produce mostly for the foreign market have some problems in getting their tax credit benefits because they do not have a corresponding amount of domestic sales. The Director of Duratex, Mr. Laerte Setubal Filho, reported in an interview with this author that they were building a new factory to produce wood- fiber sheets to be sold exclusively to the external sector. At the same time, Duratex had accumulated a huge amount of tax credits due to exports which had not yet been redeemed due to the lack of a corresponding volume of domestic sales. In 1972, to solve this problem, Duratex decided to incorporate a new firm, Deca, which produces construc- tion materials for the domestic market. In this case, therefore, the export fiscal incentives created unintended stimuli for the formation of conglomerates. 265 value of product. The ICM tax rates differ from state to state, but the rate is a uniform 17 percent of value added for industrial south central Brazil. It is subject to some upward variation in the case of poorer states and to some downward variation in the case of interstate--but not international--trade. ICM related export incentives have three characteristics. First, Article 24 of the Federal Constitution of 1967 exempts exports of manufacturers from final-stage ICM taxation. Some states also have reduced the ICM for exports of some nontraditional agricultural commodity exports. In early 1970 the States of Parana and Sao Paulo had decreased the ICM for beef exports by 60 percent and that for exported corn, rice, and soybeans by 40 percent. Second, in contrast to the IPI incentives, initially no exemption from taxation imposed at previous stages of production was offered in 1970, however, the industrial states of south central Brazil began to grant rebates from ICM taxation of raw materials used in production of manufac- tured exports on the condition that the raw materials be produced in the same state in which the export is produced. Moreover, these rebates are made in the form of credits redeemable only against other ICM liabilities of the same state. Third, since January 1970, the central and southern states have given additional credits on subsidies to exports of manufacturers at rates equal to IPI rates on respective 266 products up to a maximum of 15 percent. Imported inputs are excluded from the product value against which the ICM credit is applied (so that it relates only to value added in Brazil). These ICM credits are redeemable only in connection with other ICM liabilities. Exporters have been asking state and federal authorities to redeem accumulated ICM credits against federal tax liabilities, but it is not certain that this will be permitted. Quantification of the ICM tax benefits for exports of industrial goods can be made on the basis of the 17 percent rate applicable in the major industrial areas. The IPI (at the average rate of 12.34 percent) should be included because the ICM is calculated in addition to the IPI. Based on a ratio of value added to total value of output for all industry at around 51.2 percent, Tyler has estimated the value of the ICM exemption to average about 9.30 percent, calculated from the domestic price base. Had the ICM tax exemptions been effectively applied at all stages of production rather than only at the export stage, the incentive would have a quantitative magnitude of 17 percent of the value of the product, which includes the IPI charge. In August 1964, by implementing State Law No. 8,234 of 17 July 1964, the State of Sao Paulo already had exempted industrial exports from the payment of the ICM's predecessor, the IVC, a sales tax. The IVC in Sao Paulo at that time, and until 1967, was 6 percent of the value of 267 the product. Since Sao Paulo accounts for about one-half of Brazil's industrial exports, the national average of the IVC tax benefit for that period can be considered to be equal to one-half of the Sao Paulo IVC tax incentive of 6 percent. Income Tax Incentives Another significant tax incentive for exporters of manufactures is exemption from the income tax. There are three categories. The first exempts the firm's income earned on exports from the business income tax. The deduction is based on the exported proportion of the firm's output (Law No. 4.862, 29 November 1965, implemented in February 1967). Tyler has estimated the value of this benefit to be 4.2 percent of the domestic market price. The second allows exporters to deduct from their taxable income the following expenses in connection with export sales: commissions and interests paid abroad, exchange Operations costs, and expenditures incurred abroad for the promotion and advertising of products (Law 4.862 of 11 November 1965). The third has particular relevance for multinational companies. It either grants a reduction of the income tax levied on funds remitted abroad (such as royalties, technical assistance, and interest on loans that are duly registered with the Bank of Brazil) to a taxpayer who can prove that he has exported manufactured products or provides him with a tax refund (Decree Law No. 491, Article 8). 268 Other Indirect Tax Incentives Three other indirect tax incentives should be mentioned. First, the exporter is exempted from paying the financial operations tax on export credit, transport insurance, and export exchange operations. This incentive can be estimated to be equal to 1 percent of product value. Second, the exporter pays no sales tax on combustibles, lubricants, and electric energy related to exports of both manufactured and "extractive" products if the tax exceeds 2 percent of the price of the product. Finally, the exporter also is exempt from all governmental taxes, fees, and charges on goods going through Brazilian port facilities. The quantitative value of this incentive is small, but it indicates governmental good will toward exporters and simplifies administrative procedures. The Drawback.--The drawback allows an exporter to import raw materials and intermediary products without paying import duties if the final manufactured good is exported. The exporter is able to buy inputs at world instead of domestic prices, which may be higher because of inefficiency or the protection of infant home industry. The drawback, first decreed in 1934, remained dormant. Until it was enacted as part of the general tariff reform of 1957, (Article 34 of Law No. 3244, 14 August 1957), implemented in 1961, and modified in 1964 (Decree No. 53,967, 16 June 1964). It has three main provisions: (1) Exporters 269 need not pay duty on raw materials, semimanufactured pro- ducts, intermediary goods, and packaging materials if its plan for export production and inputs needed has been approved by the Bank of Brazil; (2) A tax credit equal to the import duties paid on goods subsequently exported in a more finished form is available in cases where exportation was not planned at the time of importation of inputs; (3) The CPA (Conselho de Politica Aduaneira) supervises refunding of import taxes paid by the exporter. Capital goods cannot be imported under the provi- sions of the drawback. A firm may submit a production plan to the government, however, and ask permission to import capital goods without the payment of duties. Complex administrative procedures coupled with the problem of having to adapt the production of goods to the imported inputs, which may differ from domestic ones, seem to have limited the use of the drawback provision at first. From 1961 to 1964 only 66 small transactions involved the drawback, but modifications in 1964 increased its use considerably. For example, in 1970 there were 627 drawback related operations, representing a total of US$43 million (fob) duty-free imports and corresponding to a sum of US$198 million (fob) in exports. This was an increase from 1969 to 1970 of approximately 335 percent.5 The number of such transactions again rose sharply in 1971, 76 percent more than in 1970. 5Banco do Brasil, Boletim, 6, No. 2 (1971). p. 13; and Banco do Brasil, Annual Report, 1971. 270 Financial Incentives Credit facilities have become a powerful instru- ment for the Brazilian government's promotion of exports of manufactured and nonmanufactured nontraditional products.6 There are provisions for a special line of short- term financing of production for export through the private banking sector at special interest rates.7 A firm does not have to be an industrial producer to borrow. Marginal increments for financial contracts are not to exceed US$200,000, a measure designed to protect small firms. To reduce risk and administrative costs, commercial banks have shown a preference for lending the tight funds available to large firms. In addition to pre-export credit facilities, post- export direct financing for export sales is provided by the Banco do Brasil and those commercial banks which are authorized to deal in exchange transactions. 6See Hesse, "Promoting of Manufactured Exports," pp. 248-50; Doellinger, et al., ExportacOes, pp. 129-56; and Tyler, "Export DiverSIfication,W_pp. 141-48. 7An exporting firm may apply to CACEX (Department of Foreign Trade of Bank of Brazil) for a certificate to utilize credit made available by Resolution 71. The firm can then go to its commercial bank and borrow funds for 120 days at an annual interest rate of 8 percent. Assuming a 10 percent real opportunity cost for capital in Brazil and 20 percent inflation (which was the approximate rate from 1969 to 1971), the 8 percent rate requests a subsidy equal to about 24 percent of the value of the financing. Resources are made available from the Central Bank to the commercial banks at an annual rediscount rate of only 4 percent and then to the exporting firm. 271 CACEX and FINAME (A BNDE subsidiary) made available long-term financing of manufactured export sales. The CACEX credit line finances up to 85 percent of cif export values on a one-year term for durable consumer goods and on terms of up to 8 years for producers' goods. The interest rate ranges between 7 and 9 percent per annum depending on the export product and the country of destination. Adding the exchange risk, the total interest cost to the borrower has been about 23 percent, similar to the case of the short- term export sales financing with commercial banks. FINAME finances all sales, either internal or external, of domes- tically produced goods. Its terms were up to three years with one year's grace. This was not sufficient, however, for export financing of capital goods. More recently, FINAME established a new line of credit from eight-year term (including two years' grace) and with nominal interest of about 28 percent. Other Credit Incentives Other credit incentives have been made available, primarily to exporters of manufactured products. First, CACEX may finance for up to 360 days 85 percent of the cif value of durable consumer and capital goods exported on consignment (Resolution 43 of CONCEX of 22 January 1969). Interest rates are: 12 percent annually plus the exchange risk. Second, CACEX may finance expenses associated with marketing operations abroad--such as marketing studies, 272 sales expenses, and advertising-~also at a 12 percent annual interest rate. (Resolution 49 of CONCEX of 11 July 1969). US$300,000 to US$500,000 is available annually for this purpose. Finally, CACEX also finances engineer- ing, economic, and other feasibility studies designed to promote exports. Institutions Many existing institutions have substantially expanded their activities related to foreign trade in the second-half of the 1960's and in the early 1970's. Most important among them are the CACEX (the foreign trade department of the Bank of Brazil, or the Carteira de Comercio Exterior), the Finance Ministry, the Ministry of Foreign Relations (Itamarati), the Central Bank, the Cus- toms Union, the Ministry of Industry and Commerce, the Ministry of Agriculture, the Association of Industries and of Trade, and especially the newly created National Associa- tion of Exporters and the National Council of Foreign Trade or CONCEX (Conselho Nacional de Comercio Exterior). CONCEX, created in October 1966, is an interministerial council which formulates, coordinates, and regulates Brazil's policies dealing with international commerce. At the end of 1972, the government also created an important national trading company. 273 Other Measures to Promote Exports: Procedure Simplification During the import substitution phase of Brazil's economic growth, the government ignored exports and even made export shipments rather difficult. Constant infla- tion, generally coupled with an overvalued exchange rate, was accompanied by incentives for investing Brazilian capital abroad. The government regarded exporters with suspicion and required licensing and copious paper work for all export operations. In 1964 the government announced that to promote exports it was simplifying export procedures, and bureaucratic requirements have been reduced substantially. Licensing has been abolished, and the export price control which sometimes is applied now is made only after shipment. Since 1965 a single form with several functions has been substituted for the numerous forms previously utilized. More important was the change in attitude toward exporters, whom the government now regarded as the key promoters of economic growth. Promotional Activities During the import substitution phase, Brazilian industries were selling only in the domestic market and were not prepared, after 1964, to promote their products and to compete in international markets. To assist exporters in these difficulties, the government extended some services through the Bank of Brazil, particularly 274 CACEX, and the Ministry of Foreign Relations (Itamaraty). CACEX is charged with promotional activities in Brazil, and Itamaraty develops foreign activities. Assisted by newly established branches of the Bank of Brazil in several major cities abroad. The offices of the regional development agency for the Northeast (SUDENE) in Salvador, Recife, and Fortaleza also are engaged in promoting export. In September 1972, in commemoration of Brazil's 150th year of independence, a private organization with strong government support organized a huge modern EXPO in Sao Paulo featuring all Brazilian export products. More than 2,000 important foreign businessmen were officially invited. "Export Corridors" In order to facilitate bulk transport for domestic, and particularly foreign, trade, the Brazilian government has undertaken a program to develop "export corridors." With an investment of US$900 million, from 1972 to 1974, five or six of the principal Brazilian ports are to be provided with highly specialized, integrated road-rail- portship systems to enable them to attain internationally acceptable levels of operation. Other measures include the mailing of samples to prospective buyers with no formalities required, the abolition of export formalities in the frontier zones, the National DevelOpment Bank (BNDE) guarantee to participants 275 in international competition, and, finally, the establish- ment by law of incentives for the formation of trading companies. APPENDIX B EXPORTS OF INDUSTRIAL GOODS: THE VARIABLES, SOURCES, AND DATA PROBLEMS 276 EXPORTS OF INDUSTRIAL GOODS: THE VARIABLES, SOURCES, AND DATA PROBLEMS Several data problems imposed significant con- straints on this research. The first is related to the measurement of the dependent variable, the exports of Brazilian industrial products. Since the early sixties, when Brazilian governments started to pay attention to the value of manufactured exports, the Department of Foreign Trade of the Banco do Brasil, CACEX, has changed the classification of exported products at least two times. Because of this, a series of quarterly data for exports of manufactures (used by W. G. Tyler and by C. V. Doellinger) from 1961 to 1970 can be found, but it has no corresponding continuation after 1970. Since 1971, CACEX/NUCEX has been publishing monthly figures of exports of semimanufactures and of manufactures under a different classification. From 1964 to 1971, only annual data were available under this classification. Accordingly, the following procedure was adopted: 1. For annual data: the values of exports of manufactured products (excluding the semiprocessed ones, such as carnauba wax, iron and steel for rerolling, pig iron, sawn wood, cocoa butter, vegetable oils, etc.) under the new CACEX/NUCEX definition were used for the period of 1964-1971. Data for the years before 1964 were not 277 278 available. Therefore, the regressions for annual data were limited to only eight observations. 2. For quarterly data: the same annual amounts as in 1 above were used. These totals were then divided into four quarters according to the percentage values of quarterly exports of manufactures under the old classifi- cation (used by W. G. Tyler) for the period of the lst quarter of 1964 to the 4th quarter ofl970. The actual values of quarterly exports of manufactures under the new CACEX/NUCEX classificationvnne then used for the period of the lst quarter of 1964 to the 2nd quarter of 1972. Annual exports of manufactures in the first classification constituted 65 percent to 85 percent of the total annual values under the new CACEX/NUCEX classification. With this procedure, which, of course, contains important limitations, a total of 33 observations was available. Unfortunately, no better alternative could be found.1 To express the value of exports in constant dollar value, the United States wholesale-price index for all commodities was used as a deflator. The values of X for 1 both annual and quarterly data are shown in Table B-1. lIn correspondence with this author, the Chief of the Nucleo de Estatistica, NUCEX/CACEX, of the Banco do Brasil, Mr. Paulo Monteiro de Araujo, wrote that it was not possible to reconstitute the whole monthly or quar- terly series of data for the period before 1970 because of several changes in the classification of products. 279 www.mv w.wN >H OON.Nm m.hN HHH nmo.mv H.VN HH mvo.ov v.HN mNH.hmH N.mOH mov.NON H mmmH Hmm.wv m.mN >H nmm.vm v.mN HHH mne.nv n.mN HH mmm.wm w.mH mmv.mmH w.mOH www.mmH H hme OON.Hv m.mN >H NHm.vm N.VN HHH www.mm m.vm HH mHm.Nm v.NN VON.va «.mOH vmo.NmH H OmmH mom.Nm m.mN >H mHO.mm O.mN HHH mvm.Hm m.VN HH www.mN O.HN OOH.hNH o.NOH an.mNH H mOmH Nmm.wm o.Nv >H HvO.NN m.mN HHH mmv.NH o.MH HH mHo.OH m.nH Nov.mm OOH Nov.mm H vme AmV AvV AmV ANV HHV ooH\Avme NnOH you sumo NHumu OOHxAN\HV mecHIOOHum ooo.Hw.m.D ucwuuou ooo.Hm.m.D (peso Haguod cam .Han ooo.Hm.m.D mHmmmHozz CH COHDHCHHOQ xmuB CH monomxm Hmsccd uo>o munoaxm NHHODMOSO Ho msHm> OOmDCOOMOQ HO manomxm AHHmuumSO poumEHuwm munOme Hmsca< moapsHoxOV mousuomHscmz mo muuoaxm Hmscqm NHumunoso Ohmsaxondmd can Hooded OnHm> umHHOQ ucmumcoo .NantvomH ”mama CH muospoum ponsuomwocmz mo musedxm m.HH~mumul.Hnm mqmde 28C) .mcacc6Hd no submacaz .ade 6:6 xmoao some 6866 emanaHnsdcs was 666H6nno umHss .uocusm was» 0» wouDOH m CH EH2 NW oHanHm>m moms NHOCHH wuo3 mosHm> usdem NHumuuosU m.umH>B .0 EmHHHHz .HHmmum on oocmm .xmuoz:xmuH www.mNH N.ON HHH ovo.HHH o.mN HH mmO.Nm N.mH vow.va v.ONH NnN.Hmm H Han mmm.mm O.mN >H mmm.om m.mN HHH HNm.mm m.ON HH www.mn v.ON mmn.wmm 0.0HH Hmm.mHv H OhmH nodumoHHHmmmHo poOun new uhonz Omv.mm v.mm >H nvn.Hn v.mN HHH nvm.Nm m.ON HH mom.wm v.mH mNm.NmN m.NHH mON.va H mme 281 The calculation of X the index of the real- 2t’ exchange rate adjusted for dollar inflation,is shown in Table B-2 for all months from January of 1963 to July of 1972. The official export (or purchase) exchange rate index was deflated by the Brazilian wholesale price index for industrial goods to obtain the index of the real exchange rate. This index was then multiplied by the United States wholesale price index for all commodities to obtain the index of real-exchange rate adjusted to dollar inflation. Figure II-l on page 67 illustrates the fluctua- tions in this index, quite wide before August 1968 and only mild since then. August l968'was chosen as a base. It may be noted that by using the Brazilian wholesale price index for industrial goods, which is more relevant for measuring the competitive position of exports of manufactures, the index of real exchange rate adjusted to dollar inflation does not decrease in value after August 1968 (as Tyler had found when using the Brazilian wholesale price index for all goods as a deflator). Tyler's calculations are shown in Table B-3 for purposes of com- parison. The reason for this difference, as already noted above (page 65), is that industrial prices increased relatively less than nonindustrial prices during 1968-1972. The index denoting the level of fiscal incentives, X is the one calculated by Tyler.2 3t' 2Tyler, "Export Diversification." 2532 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 000.0 66a 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 5oz 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 0060 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 000. 00¢ 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 :00 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 06: 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 004 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 06: 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 0000 0.00 00.00 00 00 00.00 00.00 00.0 .660 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 562 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 0.00 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 0060 0.00 00 00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 00< 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 :00 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 06: 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 004 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 062 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 660 0.00 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 0000 00V 10V 00V 00V 00V 00V 000\00Vx10V 00060000 .004 000u0000 00060000 000u00.0006 .0000 00.00.0.0 660 660060 MJOHOOHMCH umHHOQ "mmmm .XOOCH .Onm "ommm .AmV\ANV .m34 "mmmm .wacH .@s¢ “mmmm .mumm who mumm mmcmnoxm oc Umumshpoz 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.60 00.0 060 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.60 00.0 0060 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.60 00.0 000 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.60 00.0 000 0.00 00.00 00.000 00.60 00.60 00.0 :00 0.00 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.60 00.0 06: 6.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.60 00.0 006 0.600 60.00 00.000 06.00 00.00 00.0 06: 0.000 00.00 00.000 60.00 00.60 00.0 060 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 :60 0000 0.00 06.00 06.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 660 0.00 06.00 00.00 60.00 00.00 00.0 >02 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 0.00 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 0060 0.00 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 0:0 0.00 00.00 00.000 06.00 00.00 00.0 000 0.000 60.00 00.000 06.00 00.00 00.0 0:0 0.000 00.00 00.600 00.00 00.00 00.0 06: 0.000 00.00 66.000 06.00 00.00 00.0 000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.60 00.00 00.0 06: 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 00.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 0000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.06 00.00 00.0 660 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 >02 0.000 60.60 00.000 00.00 00.00 000.0 060 0.600 00.60 00.000 00.06 00.00 000.0 0060 0.000 00.60 00.000 60.06 00.00 000.0 000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 000.0 000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.66 00.00 000.0 000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 000.0 062 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 000.0 000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 000.0 062 0.000 00.00 00.00 06.00 00.00 000.0 060 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 000.0 :60 mwma 2234 0.000 0.000 60.00 00.000 00.000 00.6 :00 0.000 0.000 00.60 00.000 00.000 00.6 062 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 00.6 000 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 06.6 06: 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 00.6 660 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.600 00.000 000.6 060 0000 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 000.0 666 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 06.000 000.6 >6z 0.000 0.000 00.00 06.000 00.000 000.6 066 0.00 0.000 60.00 00.000 60.000 000.6 0060 0.000 0.600 00.00 00.000 60.000 000.6 000 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 000.6 000 0.00 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 000.0 000 6.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 000.0 06: 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 000.0 000 0.000 0.000 60.00 00.000 00.000 000.0 06: 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 000.0 660 0.00 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.600 000.0 :60 0000 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.600 000.0 660 0.00 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 060.0 >62 0.00 6.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 000.0 066 0.00 6.000 06.00 00.000 00.000 000.0 0060 0.000 0.000 00.000 00.000 00.000 00.0 000 0.00 0.000 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 000 6.00 0.000 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 000 0.60 0.00 00.60 00.00 00.00 00.0 06: 0.00 0.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.0 000 0.00 0.00 00.00 06.00 00.00 00.0 062 0.000 0.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 660 0.600 0.00 00.000 00.00 00.00 00.0 060 0000 000 000 000 000 000 000 000\000x000 00060000 .000 000n0000 000u0000 000600.0006 .0000 000.00.0.0 060 060060 Ac00u6awcH 060000 "606m .X6wcH .034 "606m .Amv\0mv .m54 "606m .ancH .054 ”606m .6u6m 000 606m 6wC6nuxm ou v6umsnncv 606m 6000016060600c3 62600020 wo x6UcH 66006 HmfluumsccH 6@C6coxm 60606050 60656090 06060000 6mC6£oxm H66m .m6u6um 6660:: 606m 6mC6£6xm H66m 606060033 0.0006um a6000ww0 wo x6©c0 .660000066--.0-0 00040 .666C065m uC6005U wO.N6>u5m .m.: 00 665660 0606>6m "Amy 00m 285 .66x6nc0 00Eocoum 06c00u6z 6.6oflsocoum 6056c5ficou mo 00 .0: x6UcH 00mv mom .6U0EQCOUM 605uC5ficou wo 665660 H6u6>6m "000 00h "6600506 00.00 00.600 00.000 00.0 660 00.00 60.000 00.000 00.0 >oz 00.00 00.000 60.000 00.0 660 00.00 00.000 00.000 00.0 6066 0.000 0.000 00.00 06.000 00.000 00.0 0:6 0.600 6.000 00.00 00.600 00.000 00.0 0:0 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 00.0 :50 0.600 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 00.0 062 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 00.0 606 6.600 0.000 00.00 06.000 00.000 00.0 662 0.600 0.000 00.00 00.600 06.000 00.0 660 0.000 0.600 00.00 00.000 06.000 00.0 :60 0000 0.000 0.000 00.00 60.000 00.600 00.0 660 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.600 00.0 >oz 0.000 0.000 00.00 06.000 00.000 06.0 660 0.000 0.000 06.00 00 600 00.000 06.0 6066 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 60.060 00.0 0:4 0.000 6.000 00.00 00.000 00.660 00.0 030 0.000 0.000 06.00 60.000 00.660 00.0 :00 0.000 0.000 60.00 00.000 00.060 00.0 06: 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 00.0 600 0.600 0.000 60.60 00.060 00.000 00.0 66: 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.060 60.000 00.0 660 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.060 60.000 00.6 :60 0000 0.000 0.000 00.60 00.660 60.000 00.6 660 0.000 0.000 00.00 00.060 00.000 00.6 >oz 0.00 0.000 60.00 00.060 00.000 00.6 660 0.000 0.000 06.00 00.060 00.000 00.6 6066 0.000 0.000 06.00 60.000 00.000 00.6 00< 6.000 0.000 00.00 00.000 00.000 00.6 000 286 m.ma H.Hom m.va m.mm m.m>a w.mwa m.mm m.m>a v.5ma ummm ooH m.mom m.oma n.vm n.ama m.ana m.om m.mma o.ana mad m.mm m.oma m.mma >.om m.mmH «.mna m.am m.mmH n.¢>a Hun e.om H.mma «.mma m.mm n.mma m.mna H.vm m.oma m.oma can No «.mma o.NnH em ¢.oma o.oma m.mm m.mma m.mma an: ma «.mma m.mha m.mm o.oma v.0ma ~.mm m.mma m.mma Hm¢ vm v.0ma o.m>a m.mm ~.vma n.mma m.moH m.mom m.nma um: mm v.¢ma o.oma q.~m «.5mH o.mma m.voa ~.HH~ ¢.oom nmm m.>m ~.mma m.vma «.Hm m.¢ma m.mma m.moa n.mam m.vom can mmma nmma mmma H.¢HH H.Hmm o.Nmm H.mma m.va m.mmm m.eh m.oma o.oma own m.maa m.vmm m.mm~ ~.eoa H.NHN m.oam m.mn H.Hoa o.oma >02 v.mm m.mma m.mma m.~aa n.mmm m.mm~ o.Nm H.mma m.mma poo n.ooa ~.¢o~ m.mma m.mHH m.ovm m.mmm H.mm m.o>a o.mna ummm >.Hoa ~.oom v.oo~ mm o.mma ¢.wma o.Nm o.nma m.oma mam m.moa m.mo~ m.mo~ H.Hma m.mmm m.vmm m.mm «.mma m.¢ma Han m.moa v.vam m.mom mma m.~mm m.mmm “.mm m.mmH m.mma can m.moa m.mHm m.oam m.mva ¢.vmm H.vmm m.voa m.aam m.HHm mm: Boa n.mam H.mH~ n.mva H.Hom m.oom o.moa m.mam m.o~m um¢ boa m.mam H.0Hm o.mm~ m.mam m.mam m.mm H.m>a m.mna um: «Ha m.n- m.v- «.mm «.mma m.mmH m.am m.mma m.mma nmm «Ha O.Hmm n.mmm m.wm m.mma ~.¢mH m.mm m.mma m.>ma can .«.H.o .¢.H.o .¢.H.o m0 no mo xmwcH .«.H.a .4.H.o.z xmwaH .¢.H.o .¢.H.o.z xmwcH .«.H.o .<.H.o.z moma vmma mmma A.Hmma .Hmuumso pma may mo ‘mmaxmuo ..m.fl ”manomxm Gawaflmmum Mom coflumamcH umaaoo Op wmpmsnwé mpmm mmcmnoxm Hmmm map mam Auoumawmo mm mUOOO Ham Hem moaum mammmaonzv ‘mEHmB pamumcou CHV .Amaoflumasoamo m.umaxev anmfiummma mumm mmcmnoxm Hmmm mnBII.MIm mqmde .mmsmmw msoflum> .cflumaasm m>ummmm Hmumwmm map vcm .mmSmmH msofium> .mowewcoom mnsucsncou «mmdmmfl msowum> .Eflumaom ‘fiflmmum OU Hmuucmu oocmm Eoum mama =.wuflaflnflxmam mumm mmcmzoxm: .Hmamh "mmousom ooa xmvcw woflumwmammmaonz .m.D x mpmu mmcmnoxm .¢.H.Q.z "mm wwumasuamo ma pH .noflumamcw HMHHOU ou wmumSflUm mumu mmcmnoxm Hmmmllm .xmvcH moHHQImHMmmHozz amaaflnmum wsu >3 mumu mmcmnoxm HmQHEoc on» mcflumHmmU an Uwumasoamo ma pH .GOHumHmcfl Hmaaoo on Umumsflvm uoc mumu mmcmnuxm Hmmmlnm .mouwmusuo AhmmHImum ..m.wv vac :fl cm>flm mum mmsam> Hafl .npcofi may no wmc umwa mzu no wou0m ca pmsu mfl Umms mumu mmzmnoxm HmcHEOG was .Umucmmmum ma mmHSpommscmE now mumu mmcmzoxm uuomxm may .muuomefl How can Ammmmoo ammoxmv mmusuommscmfilcoa now mumn map Eoum hausmflam mace mcHHmMMHQIIH 287 “mmuoz m.vm m.HmH ¢.~ma ~.Hm o.mma m.ona own m.mm m.nma H.mma H.mm “.mmfl o.moa >oz m.mm m.mma ~.mma N.¢m n.0ma m.noa poo h.mm n.5ma m.omH m.mm m.~ma m.mma ummm «.mm m.nmfl m.omH m.mm n.mma H.mna and m.ma m.mmH m.mma m.mm ¢.mo~ m.mna Haw v.om o.mma o.¢ma v.vm m.HmH v.mma «.OOH o.mo~ m.mnH saw >.~m m.nma m.mma m.mm «.mma H.5ma m.~oa m.nom m.vma was q.~m H.mma m.me mm m.vma m.mwa ~.Hoa m.qo~ H.mma um< h.mm m.mma ~.mma mm m.vaa m.mma ~.Hoa o.mo~ H.mma um: H.mm m.mma m.mma «.mm m.mmH H.owa m.mm H.Nom m.HmH nmm v.Hm m.mmH m.mmH m.mm .m.mmH m.wma mm o.mma «.mna saw Huma onma mead m.mm H.OON m.mma m.mm “.mna F.Hwa v.vm H.Hna o.HmH own v.~m m.~aa o.omH m.mm m.mna “.mwa m.¢m m.ana ~.~ma >02 m.om m.mma m.mna m.mm m.mna h.mmH m.mm ¢.mha m.mma poo 288 The proxy for world income, is the total X4t’ world imports deflated by the world trade price index. The way in which this variable was employed here differs in several respects from Tyler's use of it. First, Tyler had utilized current instead of real values; second, he used them in the form of index instead of dollars; and third, he used them in nonlog form, although the dependent variable was in log form. In this study, the log value of exports (in the order of millions of dollars) is regressed against the log value of world imports (in the order of billions of dollars)--proxy for world income--so as to obtain income elasticity values. The estimation of XSt' the proxy for capacity utilization, involved some difficulties. Following Doellinger and Tyler, the residual from the time-trend regression of Brazilian industrial production was used as a proxy. For annual data, the real value of Brazilian industrial production was available. Table C-4 shows the time-trend regression calculation. For quarterly data, however, an imperfect proxy for industrial production, the index of consumption of electric energy by industry in the 850 Paulo-Rio region, was used. In 1971, the 850 Paulo-Rio region accounted for only about 53 percent of exports of industrialized products from all regions of Brazil.3 Table B-5 shows the time-trend regression 3See CACEX, Banco do Brasil, Relatério 1971, Exportacao Brasileira, Regioes e Estados, p. 190. 289 TABLE B-4.--Residuals from Linear Time Trend Regression of Brazil's Industrial Product in Real Terms-- Annual Data: 1959-1971 (Base l949=100). Real Industrial (time) Year Product Estimated Residual x Y a? Y-s? ( l) 1959 238.5 219.8 +18.7 ( 2) 1960 261.4 243.7 +17.7 ( 3) 1961 289.2 267.6 +21.6 ( 4) 1962 311.8 291.5 +20.3 ( 5) 1963 312.4 315.4 - 3.0 ( 6) 1964 328.5 339.3 -lO.8 ( 7) 1965 313.0 363.2 -50.2 ( 8) 1966 349.6 387.1 -37.5 ( 9) 1967 360.0 411.0 -51.0 (10) 1968 415.8 434.9 -l9.1 (11) 1969 460.5 458.8 + 1.7 (12) 1970 511.8 482.7 +29.1 (13) 1971 569.1 506.6 +62.5 Regression equation: Q = 195.9 + 23.9 X Calculations: E = 7 E x = 91 2 (xi - 2) (Y1 - Y) = 4349.1 7 = 363.2 f Y = 4721.6 2 (Xi - x)2 = 182 A 2(X- - Y) (Y- - I) B = 1 _ 21 = 321211 = 23.896 2 (X1 - X) 182 a = I - 6 2 = 363.2 - 23.896 x 7 = 363.2 - 167.3 = 195.9 Source for data on Real Industrial Product: Conjuntura Econémica, Vol. 26 (November 1972). 290 TABLE B-5.-—Residuals from Linear Time Trend Regression of Brazilian Industrial Production (Proxy)-- Quarterly Data 1961-1972. I II III IV Quarterly Moving Averages of Industrial Production (Proxy) Index (Y) 1961 86.1 97.4 96.9 96.8 1962 104.6 99.2 98.8 100.1 1963 100.0 102.4 104.4 98.4 1964 101.3 103.9 104.9 107.4 1965 97.5 85.9 101.9 112.7 1966 102.4 111.4 118.4 114.2 1967 97.1 108.3 125.2 126.7 1968 118.2 125.5 137.6 144.8 1969 138.1 148.3 154.6 141.8 1970 143.9 159.9 170.7 173.0 1971 175.0 183.0 194.0 195.0 1972 191.0 205.0 Residuals from Time Trend RegressionAof Industrial Production Index (Y - Y) 1961 11.9 20.9 18.1 15.7 1962 21.2 13.5 10.8 9.8 1963 7.4 7.5 7.2 - 1.1 1964 - 0.5 - 0.2 - 1.5 - 1.3 1965 -13.5 -27.4 -13.7 - 5.2 1966 -l7.8 -11.1 - 6.2 -12.9 1967 ~32.3 -23.4 -32.2 - 9.6 1968 -20.4 -15.4 - 5.6 - 0.7 1969 - 9.7 - 1 8 2.2 -12.9 1970 -13.1 - 0.6 9.1 9.1 1971 17.9 14 5 23.2 21.9 1972 15.6 27.3 Regression equation: Y = 74.2 + 2.3 X where X = 0 for first quarter of 1961, X = 1 for second quarter 1961, etc. Source: The Industrial Production Index is based on electric power industrial consumption in the Rio-850 Paula region. Indexes are quarterly moving averages of the monthly indexes pub- lished in the Boletim do Banco Central, several issues. 291 .mlm magma mo Avv GESHOU .muuomxm mom mama mmcmnoxm Hmmu mzu ca nuCOE ou canoe Scum mmcmno mmmucmoumm "monsom m0.0 00.0 mm.a mm.m mm.m 5~.N 05.0 H.0H mmmum>¢ Hmsccm mm.0 mm.a N0.0 v0.a 05.0 00.0 mm.m vm.0H own 00.H m0.a Hm.0 0H.0 05.0 00.0 0m.mH 0m.m >02 mo.o 5m.H v0.0 mH.H 55.0 Nm.N mm.H mm.m poo Hw.0 H0.0 00.0 Hm.0 55.0 00.0 m0.H H0.m~ ummm 55.H mm.0 0m.0 05.0H 05.0 00.0 ma.0 ~0.m 05¢ mv.a vm.o vN.H mm.H mm.H mm.H 50.0 Ho.m H50 mH.o m5.a v0.m m0.m 05.0 H0.H Hm.0 mw.¢ G50 v5.0 mH.H 55.0 00.H 0v.m mm.m 0H.m mm.v 5m: v0.a 50.0 00.H mm.m 0m.m 0m.m vo.m 00.0 Had av.0 00.0 mm.a m0.m mw.a mm.m 0m.m 0m.om Hmz ov.0 Hm.0 vm.a w5.m 00.0w 0H.m mm.m mm.m th 00.0 om.N N5.N 5v.0a 0N.m 5v.5 vv.v mm.m awn H5ma 050a 000a mmma 500a 000a mwma vmma .Amcmflm uncanflz .mmcmzu mmmwcmoummv manomxm How mumm mmcmgoxm Hmmm map cfl COHPMHHm> wasuCOZII.0lmnmqm¢B 292 00.mma 5.0 I ~.mmm V5.mma m.mm m55.mv >H 0v.ama m.m I 0.mam v5.mma 0.00 00~.~m HHH mm.a~a «.mHI m.HH~ 5m.0~H H.vm 500.mv HH mm.ama v.0mI m.v0m 5m.mma v.HOH mv0.0v H mmma av.H~H 0.0 I v.00m 5m.m~H 5.00 Hmm.wv >H ma.vNH ~.~0I v.0ma 5m.m~a m.mm 5mm.vm HHH 5~.0NH v.0mI 0.50H 5m.m~a 0.0m 050.5v HH 0v.H~H m.mmI 0.0ma 5m.ama 0.00 mmm.mm H 500a a0.aaa m.~a| 5.vma 50.0HH 0.mm 00m.av >H 00.0HH ~.m I 0.00M 50.0HH H.mm Nam.vm HHH 00.HNH H.AHI 0.~0H 50.0HH N.~0H 555.mm HH 00.0ma 0.5HI v.05a 50.0HH m.moa mam.~m H mmma 5H.5MH m.m I H.Hma 50.0HH m.maa mom.mm >H 0m.vaa 5.maI 0.00a No.00a m.v0a ma0.mm HHH 00.0HH v.5mI 5.H5H voa v.00a mvm.am HH ~0.0NH m.mHI H.0ma moa 0.5HH m5v.5m H mooa 5H.0~H m.H I m.woa moa m.mma Nmm.0m >H ev.maa H.H I m.mma Hod m.vaa Hv0.~m HHH wouoawpIom.0HH m.0 I m.0ma 00H m.oaa mmv.~H HH oo.vm m.o I H.mqa OOH 0.6m mao.ma H vwma box umx uvx umx umx wax coaxlumx x nmxv xuwummmo mcoflaaflmm.m.a muuoaxu cenumaucH umflaoo ooo.am.m.a mousuomwscmz mo Hmauumsch w Aooaummmav ou mbauchcH ou owumdflpd uCMumcou CH mumuuomxm Op :OflumNHHHup XQUCH momma mpmue Hmomflm mo mecH mumm mmcmnoxm mumMSuomMscmE coAumumczemm u0w mxoum pauox >3 Umumawmo Hmmm mo xmocH mo muuoaxm Hmmm wo xoch mquQEH UHHOE .m50HIvmma "mums waumuLMQO mounuumMscmE 00 muuomxm mo wamasm m.Hfl~mum wo cofiumeumm MOW mquII.5Im mqm<9 293 .m>onm mum I Hum nuance mom "mousom mH.mmH 5.500 H0.mvH 5.00H H5v.HmH HH 05.0mH 0.00N H0.0¢H m.v0a V5v.mNH H N50H mm.mmH m.mmm H0.mvH m.NOH 00m.~mH >H om.mmH m.v5m Hm.mva N.NOH mmv.wma HHH 0N.mmH 0.00N Hm.mvH v.NOH 0v0.HHH HH mm.va H.N5m H0.mvH m.m0H mmw.mm H H5mH mm.mva m.H0m 00.HVH 5.00H www.ma >H H0.NvH 0.5mm 00.HvH m.00H mmm.0m HHH v5.v5H 0.00m 00.HVH o.NOH Hmm.mm HH N5.0vH m.mvm 00.HVH v.m0H v55.~5 H 050H m5.mva 0.0mm 00.HVH 5.NOH 000.00 >H H0.~¢H v.mvm 00.HVH m.00H 5v5.a5 HHH 00.0MH m.mvm V5.mMH 0.00H 5vm.mm HH mv.QMH m.mmm 00.mMH m.00H mom.mm H mme 294 J. O CH coHuaHun> ”dunno: mamuwbm muuanH UHuoz "wEoocH UHuoz MOM xxoum .m>onm 5Im I HIm menma 00m "ochunm 00.0 00.00H 0.00 H.H00 H0.0vH 05.00H «05.00v MImH 00.0 v0.va H.00 0.v00 00.Hv0 00.00H 005.000 nIma m0.H 0v.0vH 5.H 0.Hv0 00.00H 0H.HoH 00.0m0 mme 00.0 00.00H H.0HI 0.0H0 00.00H 00.50 00H.50H mmma 00.0 55.00H 0.HmI H.v0H 50.000 00.50 00v.mmH 500a 50.0 0v.00H 0.50I 0.00H 50.0HH 5H.HOH v00.va 000a 05.0 50.00H 0.0mI 0.05H 55.00H 00.HHH 00H.00H momH H.VH 00.0HH 0.0HI H.0mH 00.HOH 55.HHH 00v.00 v00H u5x box umx uvx u0x u0x uHx 00H Aumx . u0xv cofiumecH mwunuummscmx muflommmo mcoHHHHmmmD muuomxm ou coHumecH 000.Hm.m.0 umHHOQ Op 00 mumqume ob HmHuumsch mo 00Hu000H mo>HucmocH umHHOQ ou 000H vmumsnvd oumm coflumuwc:6mm coHumNHHHuD xovcH moHum Hmumam UWumshpm wumm acmumcou cH mmcmgomeHmmm Hmom mo xwch mo xmwcH wpmue pHuox mo xwch mocmnomeHmmm mwuquMmscmz .I Mb Umumemo mo xwvcH mo muuoaxm .H50HIV00H "mama Hmsccd .mwuqumMscmE mo muuoaxm wo >Haasm m.HH~mum mo coHumEHumm uOu mumoII.wIm mqmde 29S calculation for quarterly moving averages of the indus- trial consumption of electric power. The variable X the index of remuneration to 6t’ exporters of industrial goods, is the product of the indexes of dollar inflation adjusted real exchange rate (X2) and the level of fiscal incentives (X3). The variable X used only in regressions with 7t’ annual data (Appendix c) denotes the frequency of changes in the exchange rate. It is the annual average of the monthly percentage variation (without signs) in the index of real exchange rate. Quarterly averages of monthly variations would not account for the effects of sharp devaluations during quarters in which no devaluation occurred. This might be why Tyler obtained no signifi- cance and the theoretically incorrect sign for the coeffi- cient relating exports of manufactures and quarterly fluctuations in the real exchange rate. Table B-6 shows the calculated values of X As expected, the values 7t' for the period of minidevaluations (1969-1971) are much smaller than for the period of sharp devaluations (1964- 1968). The values used in the regressions with quarterly data are shown in Table B-7, and those used with annual data are shown in Table B-8. APPENDIX C EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON EXPORTS OF MANUFACTURES: THE REGRESSION RESULTS WITH ANNUAL DATA 296 EFFECTS OF MINIDEVALUATIONS ON EXPORTS OF MANUFACTURES: THE REGRESSION RESULTS WITH ANNUAL DATA Working with annual data to analyze exports of manufacturers offers two advantages: (1) the quality of annual data available is better than that of quarterly data; (2) lagged effects which extend for not much longer than four quarters present estimation problems of a smaller degree of difficulty. On the other hand, there is one big disadvantage: a consistent series of data is avail- able for only eight years, 1964 to 1971. As a first step, the computer was programmed to run the regression model I on the annual data from 1964 to 1971 and instructed to drOp the variables which had insignifi- cant coefficients at the 20 percent level. Equation la was obtained. All regression results in this appendix are shown in Table C-l. log X = + 1t 81 109 x log X + 3t 84 log X B2 2t + 83 4t + 85 x + 87 X + St. (I) The variables are defined in Table IV—l, Chapter IV, with the exception of X7t, which is the annual average of the monthly percentage variation (without signs) in the real 297 298 exchange rate. Measurement procedures are shown in Appen- dix B. The independent variables log X and X 4t' X5t' 7t were deleted from equation la for being insignificant (their significance, if included next in the final regres- sion, is shown in parentheses under the word deleted in Table C-l). This same model was then run for the period of only five years, from 1964 to 1968, which was Characterized by sharp adjustments in the exchange rate. Equation lb was obtained. The proxy for world income, X which is highly 4t' significant for the quarterly regressions, became insigni- ficant in the case of annual regressions. This is probably due to the smaller number of observations, and possibly, because of the greater relevance of price elasticities to explain the annual variations in Xlt' As expected, because of the longer period, the price elasticity coefficients of log X2t teal exchange rate adjusted to dollar inflation) and of log X3t (fiscal incentives for exports) are greater than in the case of quarterly regressions. The comparison between la and lb is rather precarious in view of the very small number of observations. Nevertheless, they reveal some interesting support for the main hypothesis of this work. The elasticity coefficients of both log X and 2t log X increase substantially when the three annual 3t 299 observations composing the period of mini-adjustments in the exchange rate are added to the first five years (one- third of 1968, which should be part of the additional observations, is included as part of the first period). The application of the Chow or Fisher test, however, does not confirm the hypothesis of a structural shift in the equation between the two periods: SSEa - SSEb/m F = = .0110 - .002943 = .9081 x 2 = SSEb/n - k .0029 - 3 .0029 3 F = 1.86 ‘ F3,2,.05 = 19.2. The computer was then programmed to test model II: log Xlt = 81 + 82 log xgt + 84 log X4t + 85 X5t + 87 X7t + 6t, (11) * where X6t is a weighted average of X6t and X6(t-l)' With 1 6t 6(t-l)° Insignificant variables at the 20 percent level were instructed weights of 70 percent for X and 30 percent for X to be dropped. The result is Equation 2a. 1.7 than X6t and X6(t-1) separated and also than the alterna- tive .5X6t + .5X x6t x '3X6(t-l) gave more Significant results 6(t-1)‘ 3()() .conmmuUOHOusm mo oncomnu mucouoca monumfiuoun acmuu3Icwnuso one mooo. “moo. Hmoo. oooo. oNoo. oHHo. mmm oo.~ «H.N Hm.H 5~.~ oo.~ oH.~ oo.~ oo.~ .3.o moo. mooo.ov Noo. Hoo. moo. mooo.ov ooo. mooo.ov .mwm mmv.nH HHH.HHH ~mo.mo Hmo.s~ mom.on 5o5.~o~ ~ov.n~ oo~.mo a mom. ohm. omo. 5no. voo. coo. 0H0. «on. ~m «mo. o5o. Hoo. ohm. ono. moo. «no. «50. «m Ammo. o imam. o Amos. .0 Ammo. .0 room. 0 .mno. I. up moo. I moo. I couoauc uouoaov x iso0. 0 .opo. . loco. o Amoco.o o AaIuVo . no .nuo .sno.fl o io-.~ . .mo~.o o AHH~.oH o xm + xwo .Us ooo.m ooo.o moo.v osa.o .x 00H Assn. o Imam. 0 an .8“ now Iooo.o o rsmo. o A x um x0 mmo.n ~mm.~ x mod Amos. 0 .mmm. o Amvw. o Avwm. 0 am nooo. omuoHou. ouumaofi x .mo5- o Ammo. o Aomm. 0 Imam. o _ao~. o .moo. 0 room. 0 imom. o Aomo. o Ammo. o no mHv. 00H. 000. 000. owuwHov kuwHou x vOH lama. . Amooo.o.o ion..~ o “mom.ooo on mom.m nmm.o x 00H iono. o Aoao. o 1o~m. o Iomo.m 0 on ~o~.H ons.n x moa pa..o I 66m." I oom.o I Inm.o I mom.” I HoH.~ I mo~.H I mov.m I ucmumcoo mooHIooor HsmMIvomH momHIoooH oomquomH momHIoooH HsmHIoooH oooHIoooH HooHIvooH .mno m .mnc 0 .mno m .mbo 0 .mno m .mno 0 .mno m .nno 0 gm .vo 6m .00 o .vm m .6m nm .vu an .vm no .vm 6H .cu I .mHnoauo> ucovcvmuo ecu m0 uHx 004 .muao Hascc< mounuoouscox mo muuoaxm co mcouuunHa>m©~cwx no uuuouumII.HIu uqmdh run: madamnpnvwm mounavaumnmd muchpuo ,u.m. 301 Variables log X4t' X Iand X were deleted from 5t 7t the final regression. Their significance if individually added next is shown in parentheses under the word deleted. The same model was then run for the first five years 1964-1968 to yield Equation 2b. Although less substantial than in the case of Equations 1a and lb, the comparison of Equations 2a and 2b shows an increase in the elasticity of exports with respect to the index of real remuneration to exporters (X6t) when the period of minidevaluations is included. The application of the Fisher or Chow test again does not confirm a structural shift in the equation between the two periods of 1964-1968 and 1969-1971. An explanation must now be given for the insigni- ficance of the deleted variables. The very small number of observations might be partly responsible. Equation 3 regressed on annual observations from 1964 to 1971, without deletion of variables, yields some interesting results, particularly with respect to the signs of the coefficients. The over-all regression is significant at the 1 percent level and presents a high R2 (although lower than that of la or 2a),resu1ts which are relatively good for only eight observations. The signs of the coefficients of log X log X 4t,and of X are the expected ones 6t' 7t theoretically. That of x5t indicates an interesting phenomenon, already observed. Tyler and Doellinger, as 302 shown in Chapter III, had found an inverse and significant relation between exports of manufacturers and the level of utilization of industrial capacity during the periods of 1961-1970 (Tyler) or 1963-1968 (Doellinger). Since the beginning of the mini-adjustments in the exchange rate, however, industries began to regard exports as a regular activity and not only as alternative for slackening domestic market such as happened in 1965-1967. The result of this change in attitude was that the export eXpansion contributed to the full utilization of industrial capacity during the years of great activity of the Brazilian economy after 1968. This interpretation is supported by the following: the simple correlation coefficient between log X1 and X5 is negative, equal to -.35, for the period of 1964-1968, and positive, equal to .88, for the period of 1964-1971, a dramatic change already noted with the quarterly observa- tions. In View of this, XSt should be dropped as an explanatory variable from the export function. Equation 4 is then obtained with the deletion of X The over-all significance is high as well as the 2 5t“ value of R (although still lower than that of Equation 2a). A11 coefficients, although being relatively insignificant-- perhaps due to the small size of the sample--show the expected signs. The coefficient of X4t’ the proxy for world income, shows again the lowest level of significance. An explanation for this is that the level of real remuneration 303 to exporters appears to be the overwhelming factor in determining the supply of exports, so that the level of world income does not make much difference. Given that the percentage value of Brazilian exports of manufactures is so small in relation to that of world imports, only 0.17 percent in 1971, a high significance should not be expected for the coefficient of log X4 in a very small sample size. t Finally, the coefficient of X7 shows a negative t sign, indicating that a lower degree of fluctuations in the real exchange rate had a positive effect on exports of manufactures. The low significance of the coefficient, however, does not permit a strong conclusion in this case. The best fit with quarterly observations was obtained with a model which had log X as 6t and log X4t independent variables. The same model is also significant when tested with annual data, and more so when the weighted form th = .7X6t + '3X6(t-l) is used instead of X6t' Equations 5a and 5b are the estimated regressions for two periods, 1964-1968 and 1968-1971. Contrary to what was found with quarterly regressions, changes in the level of world trade, log X4t, again do not show significance in these annual regressions. Its coefficient decreases in value and loses significance when the years 1969-1971 are added. The coefficient of log X6t’ which denotes the elas- ticity of exports of manufactures with respect to changes in the level of real remuneration to exporters, on the other 304 hand, increases in value and significance when the period of 1969-1971 is added to the regression. This indicates that the policy of mini-adjustments in the exchange rate made exporters more responsive to changes in X The 6t' application of the Chow or Fisher test, however, does not permit a strong conclusion as to the existence of a struc— tural shift in the equation after 1968. This result is rather precarious in view of the very small sample size available. Conclusion The regression analysis with annual data fell short of supporting the positive effect of minidevaluations on exports of manufactures with strong conclusive evidence. Nevertheless, it gave indications that exports of manufac- tures became more responsive to changes in the level of remuneration to exporters, both via changes in the real exchange rate and changes in the level of fiscal incentives during the period of minidevaluations. APPENDIX D EXPORTS OF BASIC PRODUCTS: THE VARIABLES, THE DATA, AND MEASUREMENT PROBLEMS 305 EXPORTS OF BASIC PRODUCTS: THE VARIABLES, THE DATA, AND MEAS UREMENT P ROBLEMS Table D-l shows the deflated values of exports of basic products other than coffee. The price index for total world imports was considered to be an appropriate deflator, as good as other alternatives such as the U.S. wholesale price index for agricultural products. There was not much difference between these two during the period covered by the study. Table D-2 shows the eXport exchange rate for basic products other than coffee deflated by the Brazilian general wholesale price index. Tables D-3 through D-5 show the construction of a weighted average price index for 28 basic products exported by Brazil. The average price index of each good in each year was weighted according to its respective participation in total basic exports. Table D-6 shows the percentage change in the real exchange rate (X7t) for exports from one month to another and the average monthly variation for each year. The greater this variation, the greater the exchange risk to the exporter. Therefore, a negative relation between X7t and log X1t should be expected. (See Appendix E.) Finally, Table D-7 shows the values of all variables used in the regression analysis. 306 307 TABLElrd.--Brazi1ian Exports of Basic Products Other than Coffee. Exports of Basic Exports of Basic Products Other Products Other Than Than Coffee in Price Index Coffee in Constant Current for total Dollar Value U.S.$1,000 (fob) World Imports (1)/(2) x 100 (l) (2) (3) 1964 460,897 100 460,897 1965 594,396 101 588,511 1966 680,507 102 667,164 “a 1967 597,732 102 586,012 1968 717,258 101 710,156 1969 983,226 104 945,410 1970 1,109,943 109 1,018,296 1971 1,215,910 115 1,057,313 1972 1,215,910 115 1,057,313 Source: For exports of basic products, Relatério, Exercicio de 1971, Banco do Brasil S.A., p. 174, and for world imports price index, International Financial Statistics, IMF, several iESues. 308 TABLEI%2.--Export Exchange Rate for Basic Products Other Than Coffee. Wholesale General Official Purchase Price Index for Real Purchase Exchange Rate Brazil Base: Exchange Rate Cr$ per U.S.$1.00 l968=100 (1)/(2) x 100 (1) (2) (3) 1964 1.224 31.15 3.929 1965 1.888 47.12 4.007 1966 2.200 64.74 3.398 1967 2.658 80.77 3.290 1968 3.411 100.00 3.411 1969 4.068 120.51 3.376 1970 4.584 146.79 3.123 1971 5.271 176.92 2.979 Source: Conjuntura Econémica, Vol. 26 (November 1972). 1 309 .55H .0 .HHmmum ow oocmm .xmu¢u .H50H m0 oHoonmxm .oHumpmHmm “mousom o5.oHH oo.mm o5.oo om.5m mo.om oH.oHH ooH II mammnxom .mm mm.5m 5H.oo o~.~o mH.mo oo.oo mo.om o~.mm ooH Hmmflm .50 m5.oHH mm.omH om.mo oo.o5 oH.mo oo.mHH oo.moH ooH 65023 no xomHn .ummmmm .om oo.00H 00H II II II II II II HHo mwsuo .m0 55.oo No.55 oH.oo m5.oo oo.ooH 5H.mHH om.oHH ooH muo mmmammcmz .om o~.~o HH.oo m5.~o H5.mo mo.oo Ho.mo mm.5m ooH muo couH .mm mo.mmH mo.oHH oo.5oH oo.mo No.0oH No.5oH mH.ooH ooH cuoo .mm HH.oom m5.mH~ mo.oom oo.mmH ~5.o5H m5.mom 5m.HoH ooH mumumnoq .Hm 5o.o~H oH.m~H mm.5HH mm.moH 5o.mo mm.HoH mo.ooH ooH mammH ooomnoe .om mo.o~H om.o~H 5m.oHH 5m.oHH ma.oHH mm.oHH 5m.moH ooH smug 0:6 6x66 .cmmnmom .oH oH.m5H oo.HoH om.ooH m5.mmH m5.mmH 5m.ooH oo.o5 ooH gang 8 mxmo .ommm couuoo .oH o~.5mH mm.mHH mm.mHH om.5HH 5m.mHH mo.mHH mo.ooH ooH smug 6:6 6x66 .muoamma .5H om.5HH ~m.mHH mm.mHH Hm.oHH o5.omH oo.o~H 5o.moH ooH mums .oH om.mo m5.mm 5m.ooH mm.mo ~o.ooH oo.omH mm.moH ooH mHmencm mHuumo COG OHUmmEOU MO mmmoflm .mH oo.ooH mo.m~H mm.ooH oo.mm 5H.HmH 0H.moH mo.mo ooH mmofla mHuumo .oH mm.mHm m5.Hmm o5.oom oo.mom om.omH o~.moa oH.moH ooH mauumo coo .mmoflm .MH oH.~mH oo.om mm.oHH mo.om 5o.5HH oo.mHH 5H.mma ooH muss Honmum .NH m~.mmH mm.m~H om.oHH mm.H~H 5o.mHH oo.omH oo.omH ooH was: 3mommo .HH Hm.moH oH.mmH Ho.omH ma.-H om.MHH om.mm oo.m5 oOH hams mmuom .oH oo.~oH om.oHH om.oo 5o.om mo.mm mm.~oH mo.HHH oOH cmuonm no omHHHao .mmmm .o 5m.HoH Hm.HmH om.~mH mm.mMH oH.moH «o.NHH oo.5m ooH mmaauom .o oH.HHH 5H.oMH Hm.moa 5o.omH mo.HHH 55.om Ho.oo ooH momma moooo .5 oH.m- mo.mo~ mo.~m~ mm.mma 55.m~H om.oHH H5.NHH oOH mamcmm .o mm.~HH mo.ooH ~5.~oH mm.mmH oo.omm 0H.ooH mm.ooH ooH 668m .m om.MMH om.omH oo.HmH mm.m~H oo.o~H mo.mMH mm.omH ooH .muscmmm .o om.~oH mm.oMH oo.mMH 5m.ooH oo.omm mo.mm~ mm.H~H ooH mnwuaHH couuoo .m H~.HNH Hm.om mo.mo oo.moH om.moH ma.om oo.5m ooH Hooz couuoo .m 5H.oo Ho.oo oo.oo m5.m5 oo.Ho mm.Ho mm.om ooH ummsm .H H5mH o5mH momH oomH 5omH oomH mooH oomH .00Huv00H mmmm Acou\wmsv uHcD mom moHHH mmmum>< msu co commm Hwnmum >3 cmuuomxm muoscoum owmmm 00 Ho mmxmwcH moHHmII.¢AHmHm¢B TABLEEP4.-Participation of Basic Products in the Total Value of Brazilian Exports (To be Used in Table D-5). 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1964 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 Total Exports 32.7 34.4 31.9 34.5 38.1 36.8 38.8 28.3 Basic Products (28) Except Coffee and Other Minor Items 4.9 4.6 Sugar 1. 310 CDHMQ‘MHVQ‘VNLONN VOOO \DHVN m0 Lnr-i (DO OH [\O Lflr-l LOO fl‘I-i KOO OH \00 \Or-l [‘0 Cotton linters Cotton wool 2. 3. 00 mm 00 r-iI-I Or—l NM 00 030‘ CH m 1!) OH OH 00 . Peanuts, green Rice 4 S 6 ON 000 O 4.6 Banana Cocoa beans Shrimps 7. OMOOOO Nmmmm ONOOO Or-il‘ COO OHI‘ OOO Beef chilled or frozen Horse meat Cashew Nuts Brazil Nuts Hides, 8. 9. 10. ll. 12. l3. 14. 15. m C 0.5 non cattle raw, 0 Hides of domestic non cattle anima Mate Cattle hides MN\O COO MN“) 00 NV 00 NV 00 05 OO V'l‘ 00 VI!) 00 LOH CO 0.3 ls Peanuts cake or bran Cotton seed, 16 O 17. 18. mmm ONH eon-I OHH VOI-l Or-Ir-l NCO CHI-4 v-I\ON OOH HCDM OOH OlfikD 00¢ OOH HNO 0 CON cake or bran cake or bran l9. Soybean, Tobacco leaves 20. 311 .05H .m ..¢.m HHmmum 00 oocmm .xmomo .H50H mo oHowoumxm .ofluwumamm ”OUHDOW Nmoo O N C O C 0 00005100000 OON mKDMMMLnl-OOWV' O 0000 O CON 0 O Q m VO‘I‘HHMkOOM O ONI‘HOOOHQ‘ Mkoln o o o loot-4m 00m 0 VFMN o V'V‘V‘l‘ . Or-‘IQO mmm O CON 0 V 0000 O IOOOH 000mm 0 o ommH «u-— fiyI— muoswonm Gamma umnuo .00 mEmuH ummoxmv mmuo A00 .HH .0 mEmuH ammoxmv mufisum mcwmum cw cmmnm .mmmwoo cmmnhom HmmHm muH£3 no x0809 .Hmmmmm HMO mcsuu who mmmcmmcmz who GOHH chow mumumnoq .00 .H0 .00 .00 .00 .50 .00 .m0 .00 .00 .00 .00 312 om.~m 00.o0 00.00 mH.Hm 00.0H 00.0H o.o 0H smug no mxmo .ommm couuoo .oH 00.05 00.H5 0H.mo oo.5o 00.00 0m.om H0.vm oH smug Ho mxmu .uscmmm .50 0o.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 o0.mv 00.H¢ om mum: .0H 00.00 00.00 0H.om 00.00 Ho.mm oo.om 00.Hm om mHmswcm mHuumo so: Ioflummsoo no mmoflm .mH 00.00 00.50 HH.00 00.0 00.00 mo.om Ho.om om mmwflz mHuumo .oH oH.mv 00.05 H0.5oH mo.H0 mo.0o 00.00 00.0o 00 mHuumo soc .3mu .mmcwm .00 00.00 oo.0v HH.~m om.05 o0.05 00.00H 00.o0 o5 mus: Haumum .mH 00.50 mm.Hw 0H.00 oo.o0 Hm.HH 00.0H mo.mH 0H muss smnmwo .HH 00.00 00.00 00.50 00.00 00.00 00.0 o.o 0 name omuom .OH 0H.H00 00.000 50.0mH 00.00 5H.00 00.05 «0.50H 00 cmuoum no 0mHHHno .mwmm .m mo.oo om.o~ oo.mo oo.5~ ~m.oH o.o H5.o o maeflnnm .o «v.000 00.000 00.050 0H.000 50.000 00.000 00.00H 0o0 momma 80000 .5 v5.00 oo.Hm mo.00 55.00 05.50 em.5o 00.00 ow mcmcmm .0 H0.mv 00.00 00.00 00.0H0 0H.00 00.0H0 00.0H0 00 800m .0 0H.oo 00.0o 00.00 00.0H mm.vm 0H.5~ 5H.0m o.o cmmum .muscmmm .o mm.oH oo.MH om.ma oo.mH oo.m~ oo.mm Hm.HmH oH mumucflH couuoo .m H0.Hmm 05.000 0H.005 mm.Hv5 05.000 05.000 v0.5mm 005 H003 :00000 .0 50.omo o0.mmm oo.oow 00.00o 0o.Hom «H.000 00.50H omm ummsm .H H50H 050H 000H 000H 500H 000H 0000 «000 .muuoaxm Hmuoa CH cowummfloflpumm mo cowuuomoum mmEHB xmmcH moflum muoswoum owmmm 00 00 muuomxm 00 meCH mowum 00 cowuosuumGOUII.WAumqm¢B 313 .0Ia 0cm 0IQ mwanma cw mumv Bonn wmpMHSOHmo "mousom 00.000 0.00 00.0000 00.50 00.000 05.00 00.50 00.000 00.005 50.000 00.000 00.000 00.000 00.00H 0.00 00.0000 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.000 00.000 H0.00 00.000 00.000 00.000 H.00 «muuomxm 05.00H0 05.000 00.00 00.00 00.00 00.000 00.H00 50.00 00.000 50.000 50.000 0.00 Hmuou ca mo.mmom 00.00 00.50 00.00 05.000 05.000 00.000 05.00 00.000 50.000 00.00 0.H0 muoswoum 00 m>onm 05.0000 00.0000 00.550 00.00 00.00 00.00 50.000 05.000 00.00 00.000 00.05 05.50 0.00 00.55 00.05 00.00 05.000 00.000 00.000 00.00 00.000 00.0 00.00 5.00 map 00 coHummHowuHmm w an 0000>H© 05.00H0 00.00 00.00 00.00 50.000 00.000 00.000 00.00 00.000 00.00 00H 0.00 00.0000 0 000 00 000 000 00 00 000 00 Mom» ms» H00 xmwcH moflum HHO mvsuo mammnmom Hmmflm 000:3 no xomHn .Hmmmmm who mmmcmmcmz muo couH CHOU muwumnoq mm>mmH ooomnoe cmun Ho wxmo .cmwnwom Edm .00 .50 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 .00 314 TABLE D-6.--Monthly Variation in the Real Exchange Rate for Exports (Percentage change, without signs). 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 Jan 5.86 4.44 7.47 5.26 10.47 2.72 2.36 0.80 Feb 8.82 2.98 3.16 20.60 2.74 1.54 0.31 0.40 Mar 80.80 6.30 2.28 1.69 3.95 1.23 0.04 0.41 Apr 6.09 3.64 2.59 3.28 2.52 1.60 0.47 1.94 May 4.85 2.10 2.53 2.40 1.89 0.77 1.15 0.74 Jun 4.66 0.51 1.01 0.79 3.05 3.04 1.76 0.15 Jul 6.61 0.67 1.58 1.59 1.23 1.24 0.24 1.49 Aug 3.02 0.13 0.98 0.78 10.78 0.30 0.92 1.77 Sept 23.81 1.03 0.98 0.77 0.51 0.98 0.01 0.41 Oct 5.25 1.89 2.82 0.77 1.15 0.94 1.37 0.03 Nov 8.38 19.50 0.94 0.76 0.18 0.91 1.62 1.66 Dec 10.54 2.33 0.93 0.76 1.04 0.92 1.25 0.35 Annual Avg. 14.1 3.79 2.27 3.29 3.29 1.35 0.96 0.85 Source: Percentage change in the real exchange rate for exports (Column (4) of Table B-2. 315 000 0000 0mcmnoxm 000m 00 x0000 .0>onm 0:0 Cu 010 000009 "000000 00.0 000.000.000 00 00.000 05 000.500.0 0500 00.0 000.000.000 00 00.000 05 000.000.0 0500 00.0 000.000.000 00 00.000 00 000.000 0000 00.0 000.000.000 00 50.000 50 000.005 0000 00.0 000.000.000 00 00.00 00 000.000 5000 50.0 000.000.000 00 05.50 00 000.500 0000 05.0 000.000.050 00 00.00 000 000.000 0000 0.00 000.000.000 000 000 000 500.000 0000 000 000 A00 000 000 A00 0000 ooo.0m.m.0 oo0\A00x000 oo0H0000 000n0000 ”0000 ooo.0m.m.0 00:0:0xm x0000 00000 000000 0039 0000 .000000 0.0.0.3 0.00nmum x0000 00000 000m :0 0000050 00003 00500 muosvoum 00:9 u0£uo 00 00000000 000ue 00003 000000u0> 00 00000000 00000 00 mu0uuoaxm 00000000 00000 0000 mmcmnoxm 00 00000000 0000002 00 0000060 00003 00 0000000c080m mo muuoaxm uuomxmv 000000 00:» 000000 0008 0mmu0>< 0m0m 00 x0000 0.00wmum 000 H0000 muosvoum 00:00 00000000 003000 x0000 00000 00000 00 muuomxm 00000 00 muuomxm .000000 0005 H0000 00050000 00000 00 00000000 000000 uuomxm 0.00nmum mo 000uME0umm How 0000u|.5A0m0m¢B APPENDIX E THE ANNUAL AVERAGE OF THE MONTHLY PERCENTAGE VARIATION (WITH NO SIGNS) IN THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE 316 THE ANNUAL AVERAGE OF THE MONTHLY PERCENTAGE VARIATION (WITH NO SIGNS) IN THE REAL EXCHANGE RATE The following situations illustrate how the variable X7t (in Chapter V and Appendix B), which is similar to variable ft (in Chapters VII and VIII) denotes the level of fluctuations in the real exchange rate and, therefore, the minidevaluations. X7t is the annual average of the monthly percen- tage change (with no signs) in the real export (purchase) exchange rate and ft is the same but for variations in the real import (sale) exchange rate. Table E-l illustrates the case of rapid inflation and one sharp devaluation. The domestic price index rises from 100 in December to 220 in December of the next year. In each month there is a ten point increase in the price index. Concomitantly, the nominal exchange rate remains pegged at the level of 100 (say, cruzeiros per dollar) from December to the next November. In December, the government decides to devalue the domestic currency sharply, and the new exchange rate becomes 220. The third and fourth columns show the real exchange rate and the monthly percentage variation (with no signs) in the real exchange rate, respectively. In this example, as expected, 317 318 the annual average of this last variable has a high value, equal to 15.14 percent. Table E-Z illustrates the case of rapid inflation, but with monthly devaluations. The nominal exchange rate is changed every month by the same rate as the domestic price index. As a result the real exchange rate remains constant and the annual average of the monthly percentage change (with no signs) in the real exchange rate is zero. Table E-3 shows the official import exchange rate deflated by the Brazilian wholesale price index and then adjusted to the U.S. dollar inflation from 1955 to 1972. Variable ft' as shown in Tables VIII-2, VIII-6, and G-l, was calculated from the data in column (3) of Table E-3. The calculation of ft is shown in Table E-4. 319 00.00 00000>< 000:00 00.000 00.000 000 000 00080000 05.0 00.50 000 000 00080>oz 00.0 00.00 000 000 0000000 00.0 00.00 000 000 000800000 00.0 00.00 000 000 0m5050 00.0 mm.mm 000 050 0090 00.0 00.00 000 000 0000 00.0 00.00 000 000 002 00.5 00.05 000 000 00000 00.5 00.05 000 000 £0002 vm.m mm.mm 000 oma mumsunmm 00.0 00.00 000 000 0005200 00.000 000 000 00080000 000 A~\00 u Amy Amy A00 0000 0mcmnoxm 00mm 0mcmnoxm 00mm mmsmnoxm x0000 00000 000000 0000 0:0 00 0000 0000802 00000800 000000 0: 50030 mmcmgo 0 000020: .0000050m>00 00000 0:0 000 000000000 00000 00 00001:.0Im mqm<9 320 0m000>0 000000 o o oo0 omm omm 00000000 c ooH o0~ o0~ 00000>oz o oo0 com. com 0000000 o oo0 o00 omH 000000000 o 000 o00 o00 000000 c oo0 o00 000 0000 o . o00 000 O00 00:0 o 000 000 omH 00: o OOH 000 Q00 00000 o ooa oma o00 0000: o oo0 000 om0 00000000 o 000 000 000 0000000 0 000 000 000 00000000 000 000000\~vnamv 000 000 0000 0m0000xm 000m 0000 000000xm 0000 0m0000xm 00000 00000 000000 000 00 00000 0000 0000802 00000800 00 0003V 000000 0000000000 000000: .m00000000>00 0000002 000 000000000 00000 00 0m00n|.~|m 00009 321 mma mom m.>m Ham Hm.m ammo. ummm mma mmm m.mm omm mH.m moa. ms¢ ova 5mm o.om «hm mo.m maa. zaan and mmv H.mm «me mo.m nma. mash mma omv m.mm mom mm.~ m¢a. mm: com ome m.mm mam mm.~ mva. uma mva mmm m.¢m mmm mu.~ nod. um: mma adv o.¢m «me vn.~ mad. 9mm ova mmm m.mm Ham mm.~ Hoa. can mmma «ma mam >.mm wwm ¢m.~ memo. own ¢ea «mm m.mm mum mm.~ mmmo. >oz mwa 5mm m.mm omm mm.~ ooa. uoo mva m¢m o.¢m Hum mm.m mnmo. ummm mod mam m.mm mme mm.~ oaa. mam mma omm o.mm mow ~m.m moae mash “ma ¢mm m.mm «av m¢.m moa. mcsn mma omm m.~m mmw mq.~ moa. mm: Hma «mm o.mm «we om.~ med. um< Hod mam o.Nm nmv mv.~ moa. um: mma Hmm m.mm mmm mv.~ mnmo. nmm mad mmm n.mm mom nv.~ omho. can mmma on Amy Aqv Amy Amy Adv coaummma ooa\mavvxamvg xmccH woflum ooaxfiA~v\AHvu xmccH moflum mumm .ummm "mmmm muHOQEH mHMmmaonz muuomEH adammaonz mmcmzoxm coflumamcH umaaoo How coflpmamcH .4.m.p “ow mpmm m.aflnmum uuomEH 0» cmumsflv< nmafloo on mmcmnoxm Hmmm momum>m mumm mommaoxm cmpmsflcm mumm manage: Hmmm mo xmwcH mmamnoxm Hmmm .mnmaummma “cOHumamca umaaoa on Umumsnwm mumm mmcmnoxm Hmmm unomEH mnu cam mumm mmcmnoxm unomEH Hafioflmmo mzeul.m1m mqmfia 322 va hma NON mam mud 05H mod mma HmH GHH mma HmH NOH mm 00H boa hm moa 00H Hoa NOH mm 00H hm «OH moa HHH .\.. mhv mmv mmv mmm mmv mav Haw mHv vv¢ mmm mhm Hmm omm mmm mvm mmm mmm mmm mvm hem omN mvm mvm mmm «mm 0mm mum m.ooH m.00H «.OOH N.0¢H N.00H m.ooa m.ooH m.ooa «.OOH h.ooa N.00H H.OOH h.mm v.mm N.mm m.mm h.mm m.mm m.mm m.mm m.mm «.mm m.mm v.mm m.hm m.hm m.hm — o .v.;. mhv hmw mmv mmm mm¢ haw oav NHv Nev omm mhm Hmm Hmm mmm hwm mmm mmm com mvm 0mm mmm bvm mvm New com mom omm ov.v mm.¢ va.v mm.m mm.m wh.m mm.m vm.m hm.m Hm.m mv.m mv.m v¢.m mm.m mm.m hm.m mm.m ov.m hm.m hm.m mm.m vv.m m¢.m hv.m mm.m Hm.m hm.m mom. mma. mom. cam. mod. wma. omH. omH. mmH. hma. Hma. NHH. mwmo. vmbo. ommo. wmmo. memo. mmmo. Oemo. vvmo. hmmo. mvmo. mwmo. vmo. mmmo. ammo. name. 000 >02 poo ummm 0:4 hand wash >02 “mm um: 002 can mmmH 000 >02 uoo 00mm mad wash mash H24 H02 002 :00 hmmH Own >02 000 ...,z. a; Nyavnr‘ 323 mma mam m.ooa mam m~.n mmm. umwm «ma mum m.ooa ham hm.m mum. and aea mam m.oca mam mm.m mmm. mash mva 5mm o.ooa mmm am.m «ma. «can ama chm h.ooa 50m mo.m mam. an: vma bum o.aoa mum ma.» mam. “ma oma mmm o.aoa mum mq.o «am. am: mma mmm q.ooa 5mm mm.m «an. nmm ova mam a.ooa mam aa.m mom. :mn coma mva mam o.ooa mam 00.0 mom. can naa mmm o.ooa mmm om.m mam. >oz mma mam ~.ooa mam ~5.m «mm. 000 mma mam n.ooa mmm am.m mam. ummm mma mam m.ooa «mm mv.m 55a” mam vva mmm o.ooa amm ma.m mma. wash maa mwm n.ooa amm no.m mma. masn ooa amm m.ooa 5mm ao.m «ma. an: mma mma o.aoa mmv mm.a mam. and hem mom h.ooa com mm.a Nam. umz mmm mmm o.ooa mum am.a 0mm. nmm omm mmm o.ooa mam nm.v mam. can mmma Amy Amy Aav Amy Amy Aav ooaummma ooa\a2avxamvg xmcca moaum ooaxaamvxhavg xmnca moaum mumm .ummm "mmmm muHOQEH mammmaonz muHOQEH mammmaosz mmcmsoxm acaumamca umaaoo now coaumamca .¢.m.: now mumm m.aaumum unomEa 0p vmumSnUm HMHHOD 0p mmcmsoxm Hmwm mmmam>< mumm mmcmnoxm cmumsflwd mumm manucoz ammm m0 xmvcH mmcmnoxm ammm .wmacaucooun.mum mamas 324 n". v moa «Ha NNH mNH HHH Noa moa Hoa mm OOH Hoa MOH moa HHH moa mad vHH maa mHH mNH «ma mma mad mHH HNH vNH .m‘ -—- wmm 0mm oom mam mnm Hmm mmm hvm New mvm mvm mmm 5mm mum mmm Hmm mum mmm mmm mom mmm Hmm mmm omm mmm mom ..vu v.ooa h.ooa m.ooa N.HOH m.ooH v.ooH o.ooa N.ooH v.00H h.ooa h.ooa m.ooa v.00H o.ooa o.ooa o.ooa H.OOH m.mm m.mm m.mm m.ooa o.ooH O.Hoa m.ooa m.ooa h.ooa h.ooa . -....— . ..A.— 1.33— mom mum mmm Nam Hum 0mm mmm mvm mvm mvm mvm omN mom mum mwm Ham mum mmm Ham mom mmm mmm mmm mmm «mm Hom Q K: q ' A -‘ .*‘ 4‘" f m.hH H.5H m.mH v.mH o.mH h.va o.vH m.mH H.mH o.mH m.NH h.NH m.HH m.HH H.HH H.OH hm.m NH.m hm.m Hm.m hm.m mm.m mo.m oa.m vm.h mh.h Hm.h mbv. mhv. mhw. omv. hoe. 5mm. Hmm. mmm. mam. mam. mam. mam. ham. «am. mam. 0mm. Ohm. mmm. How. Ohm. vmm. ANN. mmm. mmm. mmm. mmm. 000 >02 poo ummm 0:4 Mann 0:30 mm: Had am: 002 :00 Noma 000 >02 uoo ummm 09¢ wasn 0050 HQ< am: 002 :00 Hmma 000 >02 #00 a.‘p/ \tynnrn. rid-44‘: 325 mma mom n.ooa oom o.mm mmmaa ummm mm mvm m.ooa new o.am vmm.a mad ooa we” v.ooa mam m.mv oo~.a mash moa mmm o.ooa mmm m.mv oom.a 00:0 moa mmm a.ooa mmm v.eq vaa.a was mm cam m.ooa mom m.m¢ cam. um¢ mm mam v.ooa mam m.a¢ com. an: «m amm m.ooa omm m.mm mam. non ooa mam o.aoa mvm m.mm «am. can vuma mm mmm m.ooa «am m.~m omn. 000 mm mam n.ooa mam o.om mmm. >oz «a omm m.ooa mmu m.mm mum. poo aoa mmm m.ooa mmm m.>m mop. ummm aoa mmm a.ooa mmm m.mm new, mum moa 5mm m.ooa mmm «.mm mam. mash moa 5mm m.ooa mmm m.am 0mm. mash moa mom o.ooa mwm a.m~ omm. mm: Noa amm h.mm amm ~.- mmm. Ham mm ovm m.mm own a.- amm. an: ooa mam m.ooa «an m.o~ mom. nmm ooa «am m.ooa mam m.ma muv. :mh mmma Amy Amv Aav Amy any Aav ooanmmma ooa\m2vvxamvg xmcca moaum ooaxmA~V\Aavg xmwaa moaum mumm .ummm “0mmm muuomEH mammmaonz muHOQEH mammmaosz mmcmnoxm COHpmHmcH Hmaaoo Mom COHumHmGH .¢.m.D How mumm m.aflumam pHOQEH 0» UmumSnvm umaaoo 0p mmcmnoxm ammm mmmam>m mumm mmamnoxm cmumsnc« mumm manpcoz H002 m0 xmvcH mmcmsoxm Hmmm .UGDCHHGOUII.MIm mqmdfi 326 hm hm hm Hm mm mm mm mm ooa ¢0H boa med mad OHH ooa Hoa NOH voa boa boa moa moa vHH maa moa OHH mad NHN mam @HN mmm mmm mmm mmm mmm mvm mmm me vmm mmm mom vvm hvm Hmm mmm mmm mom mmm mmm mum mmm mmm Ohm mmm m.moa m.moa «.moa m.on m.moH «.moa h.moa m.moa v.moa ¢.moa v.moa w.¢oa H.¢oa m.m9H H.m0H o.moa m.~oa m.moa m.moa H.Noa h.Hoa m.Hoa N.Hoa O.HOH >.ooa b.ooa m.ooa com com NON new HHN mam mmm mmm mmm mwm mvm mmm fihm 0mm mMN ovm vvm mom «mm 5mm 0mm vow ohm 0mm mwm mom mmm :v“ NN" HHH HHH OHH boa mod MOH m.mm m.hm H.mm m.om m.mm m.hm m.om N.mb o.mh m.wh m.mh N.v> m.mh m.Hh h.o> m.mo H.5o o.mm o.mm o.ow m.mm NN.N NN.N NN.N NN.N NN.N NN.N NN.N omm.m omN.N ONN.N mHN.m mHN.N mam.m Hmo.m mvm.H mvm.H ovm.H ovm.a ovm.a ovm.H ovm.H m¢m.a Hmm.a omm.a mmm.a oaw.a oam.a ' I- .‘E . 000 >02 poo ummm ms< wash 0:50 >02 Had am: 002 cm0 mmma 009 >02 poo ummm and mama mash >02 HQ< H02 002 000 mmmH Own >02 poo 327 ooa mam a.moa mmm mma oom.m ummm mm mum n.moa pom mma oom.m and aa vNN a.moa mo~ hma o-.m mama mm mmw h.moa mom mma m-.m wash «a can m.moa Nam mma am~.m an: mm mmm m.moa «an oma oa~.m “mm mm mam «.moa 5am mqa oam.m um: mm mm~ o.moa a- mqa oa~.m gum ooa «cm ~.>oa mmm ava oa~.m can mmma hm mam m.ooa com mma man.m own hm vam ~.ooa aom mma ma>.~ >02 mm ham a.moa «om mma mah.~ 000 am mam m.moa aom oma mah.m ummm am mam a.moa oam mma mandm ms< mm mam m.moa Nam mma man.m wash mm mam m.moa omm mma man.~ mash mm mam m.moa mmm «Na ma~.~ an: mm amm m.moa mmm mma mah.m 00¢ mm mmm h.moa mmm oma ma>.~ um: mm mmm o.moa omm maa amm.~ nmm mm mom «.moa ama oaa mm.m can nmma Amy Amy Avv Amv Amy “av ooanmwma ooa\a2vvxfimvg xmwca moaum ooaxaA~V\Aavg xmwca moaum mumm .ummm "mmmm muaomEH mammmaonz muHOQEH mammmaonz mmcmnoxm ceaumawca Hmaaoo Hem coaumamca .<.m.s How mumm m.aaumum “HomEa 00 UmumSmUG amaaow 0p mmcmnoxm Hmmm mmmam>4 mama mmcmsoxm mmpmsflua mumm wagucoz Hmmm m0 waGH mmcmsoxm Hmmm .UmDGHHCOUII.mIm mqmdfi 328 mm mm mm om mm mm mm mm mm mm um um OOH mm hm mm mm Hoa NOH moa voa voa Hoa OOH Hoa mm mm A... d .-.. —: mmm Nmm hmm omm mmm mmm mmm mmm ovm mmm mmm mmm mvm mmm mmm hmm ovm hvm Hmm «mm vmm mmm mum vvm hem ovm Nvm 5.5HH w.hHH h.bHH 5.5HH m.bHH o.NHH 0.5HH b.0HH m.wHH m.mHH m.mHH m.mHH H.mHH h.mHH o.vaa w.MHH v.maa m.maa N.mHH m.mHH m.HHH h.aaa H.HHH n.0aa m.m0H m.m0H H.moa \‘\- 0...! .....- vovav— -I: a mma baa mmH mmH mma oom mom mom mom mom mom mom MHN mom mom mom NAN mam ANN mmm mmm mmm mmm omm mNN mam HNN ‘23..- ....N :ava. new mvm vvm own mmm omm wmm HNN mam mam mam NAN mom vow How mmH NmH mma mma mud mha vhH mha vba ova ona boa omm.¢ omm.v .omh.q omm.¢ omm.v oam.v omm.v omm.v omv.v om¢.v mov.v omm.v mam.v vmm.v mom.v mmo.v moo.v Hmo.v omo.v m~o.¢ ooo.v wmm.m mmm.m omm.m mam.m mmw.m oow.m own >02 #00 000m 054 wash 0050 mm: 00¢ an: 002 can chad own >02 #00 000m mad hash 0000 >02 and am: 002 can mmma 000 >02 poo 329 mm ham m.n~a aha mam mao.m “mom ma mum a.n~a aha mmm mom.m mam am omm m.m~a ama nmm avm.m wash mm mmm o.oma «ma mmm mam.m mash mm «mm m.m~a mma mam mmm.m mm: mm mmm m.¢ma qma ham mom.m Had vm omm m.v~a mma vam mam.m um: mm mmm v.¢ma nma mom mms.m 002 cm amm m.m~a nma mom vmw.m can mhma mm mmm «.mma oma ham mmo.m 000 vm amm v.a~a oma vmm wmm.m >02 vm omm m.a~a oma omm mom.m 000 «m amm v.ama oma 5mm mmv.m ummm «a amm m.ama oma mam ommqm mz< mm mmm m.a~a mma amm mmm.m masn mm mmm m.ama mma mum mmm.m 0:00 mm mam n.0ma mma cum oma.m was em amm H.ONH mma mom oaa.m and mm mmm m.maa qma awn omo.m mm: mm «mm m.maa mma mmm mmm.v 002 mm «mm m.maa baa amm omm.v cub anma Amy Amy Avv Amy Amy Aav oo.ummma ooa\afiavxfimvu xmwca moaum ooaxaamvaavg xmwca moaum mpmm .ummm “mmmm manomfia mHMmMHOSZ muHOQEH mammmaonz mmcmnoxm coaumamzH HMHHOQ How coaumawcH .<.m.D How mumm m.aanmam uaomEH 0p wmumsnvd amaaov 0p mmcmzoxm ammm . mmmam>d mumm mmcmnoxm Umpmnflwm mumm manucoz Hmmm m0 xmvcH wmcmsoxm Hmmm .wmscaucoouu.mum mamme 330 . mmwflmmfl HMHG>mm hm mam Amhma HmQEm>OZV mm .moaumaumum HMHOGMCHm HmcoaumcumucH “Avv Mom .Amnma coumzv .moafiwcoom musuGSncou m0 ma xmwcH "Amy mom .Amnma nounZV hm new “0:050Hmmsm mhma nmnEm>02v mm .moaewcoom manuCShmou "Aav Mom “mmousom vm mm mm V: ..‘v «.3 -. ..- Hmm hmm mmm m.oma o.mmH N.BNH NBA 55H 55H mvm HmH.w OQQ mvm VHH.m >02 Nvm mmo.m #00 2.; NW ”3..“ may 331 J Apt va.e mm.v mm.v mm.m m~.m vm.m hb.v no.HH Hm.w mm.da mmmuw>¢ mH.m mw.v mm.m vo.m mo.m vm.m om.m m~.~ mm.m Hm.¢H 000 mm.m no.5 hm.a mm.m 5v.n mw.n mm.¢ oo.m m~.o mo.¢m >02 om.o~ na.v om.» ev.v mn.o mm.m ah.m hm.m mv.~ mm.m poo o.o ma.ma om.v nm.m mm.ma mm.o~ vm.aa vv.> HB.~H mm.v ummm o.o ov.m Na.m mm.v mm.n wo.m mv.m mw.m am.m mm.mH mad mm.o bv.m «O.H mm.m mn.m an.a mv.v mo.ma om.a om.ma hash mv.v m~.m om.v hm.m mn.m mv.o ov.o oa.oa om.a hm.a 0:50 nn.o mm.a ah.m aw.a wm.ma mn.m mH.H mm.a nv.o hm.v >02 mm.v mm.o o.o mm.a om.ma mm.ma mv.m mm.mm on.o mm.na and vw.a av.o om.ma mv.ma am.m oo.v om.o mm.aa vm.ma mm.m umz mm.o om.a In: mv.a vm.> mm.ma mm.m Hm.ma mm.ma mo.ma nmm mm.m No.m vn.H mn.H vm.ma mm.nm No.0 05.0H nm.o nm.m awn mmma mmma Hmma coma mmma mmma hmma mmma mmma vmma .muHOQEH u0m mumm mmcmnoxm ammm 0:» ca mmcmsu mmmucmoawm >a£ucozll.vum mqmds 332 .AMIH manna m0 m cEsHOUV chcw momma mammma0n3 cmaaflnmum 0:» ha 000a>a0 mama mmamzuxo uuomfia mmmuo>m hanucoe 0:» ma mama wmcmnoxm ammm mm.o mm.o m~.a mm.a vm.m mm.~ me.~ a~.m «a.» Aumv mmmaw>< o.o o.o am.o o¢.~ «m.~ mm.o o.o mm.m om.a own o.o o.o mo.~ mv.o mm.a mv.a mm.o ma.oa m~.m >oz mm.o o.o mo.a m«.m mm.a mm.m ~v.~ mo.a mm.m poo o.o o.o am.a mm.a om.m mm.o mm.a mm.a mm.m~ ummm mm.a mo.a oo.a mm.~ mm.o am.o mm.a am.a aa.o ms¢ mm.a mm.o mm.o mm.a mv.a mm.m mm.m mm.~ ma.m mash am.o mm.a ma.a mm.a mm.a am.a mm.m ma.a mm.~ mash mm.o mm.o ma.o mm.o mm.o 00.0 mm.a ma.a mo.am mm: mm.o mm.o mv.a am.o mm.a mm.a oo.m am.a mm.~ “mm mo.a mo.a mm.o mm.m am.a mm.m a~.a am.m mm.m um: o.o am.o o.o mm.a mo.m ma.ma mm.a mm.a mm.m nmm mm.a am.o mm.m -.~ oo.ma om.a mo.m mm.m mo.m can mmma amma omma mmma mmma mmma mmma mmma mmma APPENDIX F DATA USED IN THE ANALYSIS OF BRAZILIAN IMPORTS 333 334 TABLE F-1.--Brazi1's Import Coefficient Calculated in Current Prices. 1947-1972. Gross Domestic Import Product Imports Coefficient Year (Million CR$) (Million CR$) Imports/GDP 1947 164.9 22.8 13.8 1948 194.6 21.0 10.8 1949 229.9 20.6 9.0 1950 272.1 20.3 7.5 1951 322.7 37.2 11.5 1952 397.3 37.2 9.4 1953 469.5 25.1 5.3 1954 627.4 55.2 8.8 1955 783.4 60.2 7.7 1956 995.9 71.6 7.2 1957 1,218.0 86.5 7.1 1958 1,457.5 103.3 7.1 1959 1,989.6 161.3 8.1 1960 2,755.7 201.2 7.3 1961 4,052.1 299.4 7.4 1962 6,601.4 511.7 7.8 1963 11,928.6 782.2 6.6 1964 23,055.9 1,242.9 5.4 1965 38,817.6 1,929.6 5.0 1966 53,724.1 3,264.8 6.1 1967 71,486.3 4,291.9 6.0 1968 99,879.3 6,826.2 6.8 1969 133,116.9 8,982.0 6.7 1970 174,624.1 12,903.6 7.4 1971 234,005.3 19,216.1 8.2 1972 Source: Current imports from CACEX, Banco do Brasil, Brasil, Comércio Exterior--Foreign Trade 1971, and current GDP from Conjuntura Economica, 26 (November 1972). 335 TABLE F-2.--Brazil's Import Coefficient Calculated in Constant Prices of 1949, 1947-1971. Import GDP Imports Coefficient Year (1949 prices) (1949 Prices) Imports/GDP % 1947 200.7 27.1 13.5 1948 215.6 22.9 10.6 1949 229.9 20.6 9.0 1950 244.8 18.0 7.4 1951 259.3 27.4 10.6 1952 281.9 24.8 8.8 1953 289.0 14.5 5.0 1954 318.2 24.5 7.7 1955 340.0 23.7 7.0 1956 350.8 23.6 6.3 1957 379.1 25.4 6.7 1958 408.3 27.0 6.6 1959 431.1 30.7 7.1 1960 472.9 29.2 6.2 1961 521.6 31.4 6.0 1962 549.0 35.0 6.4 1963 557.5 30.8 5.6 1964 573.8 25.6 4.5 1965 589.5 26.3 4.5 1966 619.6 32.3 5.2 1967 649.2 34.1 5.3 1968 709.7 43.8 6.2 1969 773.6 47.8 6.2 1970 847.2 56.3 6.6 1971 942.9 69.6 7.4 Sources: CACEX, Banco do Brasil, Brasil, Comercio Exterior-- Foreign Trade 1971, and Conjuntura Econémica, 26 (November 1972). GDP values were deflated by the national income implicit deflator and imports by the global supply wholesale price index for all commodities (Index 16 0f Conjuntura Econ6mica). 336 TABLE F-3.*—Brazil's Import Coefficient in Several Periods. Import Coefficient Current Constant Real GDP Cruzeiros Cruzeiros Annual Average Period of 1949 Growth Rate % % 1947-52 10.3 10.0 7.04* 1953-57 7.2 6.5 5.68 1958-61 7.5 6.5 8.33 1962-67 6.1 5.2 3.72 1968—71 7.3 6.6 9.78 Source: See Tables F-l and F-2. *Excludes 1947. £337 .aammum 00 oocmm .xmo4u .anma Cauoumaom "mouzom a.omm.m m.wom.m ~.mmm.a H.mmm.a m.a¢v.a «.mom.a o.ovm v.wmo.a amuoe v.mm~ m.mmm o.vma a.mqa H.OHH m.mm o.om m.aw msomcmaamomflz m.am~.a m.mom m.man m.mow n.5mv m.amm m.n~m o.~m~ anaumums uuommcmuu .aMaumumE uauuomam uucwEmasom cam unmeasomz v.mmv o.omm m.nm~ m.ao~ h.mnH m.mma m.maa m.maa muoscoum can mamume cOEEOU 0.5m o.om m.vm m.mm h.oa m.v o.v o.m mooom maauxmu 0:0 mawuxma a.mmm a.omv m.aam m.aam a.m~m o.mam o.nwa m.mva muosooum namnu can uwnndu oaumcucxm 0:0 amazon: "mmauumscca owumamu can amoa60n0 mo muoocoum a.mma m.m~a m.maa o.maa o.Nm m00020aa00ma2 o.omm m.mna m.mva m.nma v.aaa Esmaouumm n.mov a.aom o.omm m.mmm o.vma v.wo~ v.mma ~.mom muoocoum amumcaz a.ma m.aa v.m m.ma m.m m.~ v.a m.~ muosooud mua com 000000» .umm00a> 0cm aocooam .oaooaa .mwomu0>wn "muumoGCa 000w mo muosooum m.mma o.wma a.mma v.mma a.mma a.mm m.mo m.mm moowaaawoma: m.noa m.moa m.vma n.mma m.mma o.Nqa o.vaa o.ona ummnz o.mmm m.mmm m.mwm a.om~ m.amm a.ov~ m.mma m.mmm mooooum manmumom> 0cm amEac4 ocm x000m0>aa amma omma mmma mwma nwma wwma mmma voma .ammauvmma .Amomv macaaaae mm: muuooea awaaammum--.vnm mommy 338 .vlm_0anme "00a00m m.mm¢ o.onm m.mmm m.avm m.mba m.mma H.mm ooa muaomaa H0£DOIIm a.mmv m.mam m.mvm v.0am m.mma v.mma m.mn ooa amaa0ume uuommcmau “aman0uma 0aa000a0 “000Emaso0 0:0 >H0canomznln «.mmm o.omm m.m~m «.mma m.mma m.mma m.aoa ooa muoswonm 0:0 mamu0E COEEoollm o.owaa o.omn o.mmv o.mmm o.vam o.om o.om ooa 00000 0Haux0u 000 0kux0anlm n.mmm m.mmm m.mom v.mo~ m.HhH H.5va m.~aa ooa mausooum aa0nu new H0QQDH 0au0£uc>m 000 amusumc “m0aaumsoaa o0uma0a paw aman0£0 m0 muooooumlnv m.mma m.mva m.¢ma o.Nma n.mm n.mm a.om ooa mausooam Hma0cazunm 0.5mm m.mov m.mmm ~.mmv oom a.mm m.m¢ ooa muosooam mum 0:0 0000000 .amm0cfl> 000 Honooam panoaa .m0mma0>0n "may Immoca ©00m mo muosooamuum m.moa o.ooa m.moa m.maa m.moa o.mm m.on ooa 0050000 0anmu0m0> pom Hosacm cam x00000>malna m.mmm m.omm m.mma m.ona n.mma o.oma 0.0m ooa muaomEH amuoe mnma ahma onma mmma mmma hmma mmma mmma coma .ooa n «mma "x0UcH 000m 0H00852 x0©cH .anmasvmma “muaomEH cmaaaumamul.mlh mummy 339 .vn0H0H00B ”000500 0.m m.mm m.ma m.O 0.x H.0 N.0m o.NH m.O v.OH m.h h.mm O.mH v.0 N.MH O.m 0.Nm 0.0H m.ma h.O 0.0 v.0m 0.mH m.mH o.o m.0H v.0 O.hN m.mH N.O «.ma h.m m.vm o.om N.O 0.m 0.0m m.OH h.ma m.0H m.O 0000050 00000::0 00000008 000000000 .00000008 00000000 «0508 100500 000 000000002110 00050000 000 000006 GOEEOUII0 00000 0000x00 000 0H00x09||m 00050000 00000 000 000050 000000000 000 H005000 00000005000 0000000 000 00008000 00 00050000||v 00050000 H000cflz|um 00050000 000 000 0000000 .000000> 000 0000000 0050HH .000000>00 "000 105000 0000 00 00050000||m 0050000 0H000000> 000 a0E000 0G0 000000>HAIIH OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH OOH 0000080 H0009 mmma Ahma Ohma 000a mmma hmma mmma mwma vmma .ammaavmma 000005a a00oe 00 05000 0000 00 00000 0000000000 .00050000 00 005000 00 00000EH 00HH0000m|I.0I0 00049 340 n0 «an 900 0 000 a vuw m v.00 Noe n o.mou o.oa ~00 « me «had ~A vuw who 0 om~ 0 000 N w.hou vnv ~ 0.000 o.naa man ~ «A 0500 a» 50 u mmm mmm vvm a «.ho man u o.nou o.ood Han n 00 «mod ca 000: 900 vnv «an H o.Na mna a o.mon ~.ha an: 0 ca 0000 a n~ I awn van «no A 0.0. «an H o.NoH 0.00 vmu a a hood . 00 00v th mvn a a.oa was a 9.09 p.05 «vs A a moon n v00 now 00m can A «.mou own d 5.50 o.no~ can a 0 meme 0 000 vm 000 nov A o.mou «ov a v.00 o.Noa on. A 0 wood 0 now. Non v0 wav 0 w.mo own a 0.00 ”.00 oo- 0 m Mona v 0.0- ms 00 u own A o.m¢ unv A n.so m.mo mam a v «004 n am 00 0'0 nmv 0 o.~o~ vmv a v.00 0.00 now a n moan ~ 0 «0 0m «mm a {v.00 awn a o.va m.no can a N owaa 0 l..- 3.. ..-: 3m 0 0.; 3n 0 «.3 0:00 «2 0 0 003 mama 0000 $7512 3-3318 37131: $13 $873. $00621: E 5 3 .3 ““0me .onammmo Ea mmflw guano: ”mm? 33? £25 Hummus .02 £0on 0:0 :0 000 :0 0:000:0050 uo wfihoa 00 00000 00 00000 . 000:000 >0 Idocunu mm 00 unflcn uo nuuoaku uo nuuoaxn mmma 0000004 000000 «0 00300 0000000050 .00 ac oncozu ooa I hw\moma 000000 uo x0000 .000080 00 00000000 0:0 0000000 no 00300 0000000050:|.hn0 Nqn<8 341 ma mam! dean aHvI Ovvi «MN HmN mad mad ma NH has! own: omnl hwnl Gad aow «we awd NA ad Haw! ovwl NBNI owNI and omd OHM 0nd HA 3 Sm- 2? $7 :7 2: 2: 3 a... S m 00ml hhmi NMHI mndl wed cad mh hh a m onwo hmvl haul FHA- uh uh mm mm a h 0": Omvl mm I ma l VOA NOH 00 an F m ale mmNI OMHI mNHI ow mm vm Nm u m MAN: NAN! vmdl nmat nv nv mm mm n v com! ole final "MA! on mm om av v n Noni ovml HVHI wnal mm Nu mm mm M N mvml ham! NVHI mmal Hmd nvd mm om N a movl vmnl Nvdl QMHI ONH bud nv NC A E l E n ' I 332: :2 3.: 3:03 3: 3: digs 2: a: .3 S 3.: 3: .oz cabana mwu«um meowum mouwum nouwum mouwum «vodka noowum .oz nw\moma u< ucwuusu nw\mmma ad uCQuHDU ho\mwm~ 0‘ vcouhsv hw\mwoa u‘ udmuudu wamfluquEOUncoz mamw0quEou «HmwuuoEEOUtcoz NanaouwaEOU nucw8>am nun«IOI¢ noow>uom 63:350-- .7m ”39; 342 uuoafiA mo ququou ecu cA wocenu a .AmuAaoo uo soauca u¢c can .mCOMuMNAUAOEd .mwoA>u0m .woouu mo mauwu .mw umnhv .mucofiumw>c«uu can acofiuuuauAOEd mangaocmn $665me No 8533 Unaccwum may we new”: .355 “amwouogoocoz .mocmusmcw one coAuoluoaucduu "nuo«>uom HuwouoEEOUN .Iucufiuav>:Aax movaaoxmd .aowamcoUm ausucmfidoo .0 .AAu>AAouanou .AoA u:- sAA .oc nouoncA "An. can Aw. acaquu Awnuun 06 uuuunou Oncdn "nouusom AA o.o A omo n- mvw m- mmm A .mm A aoo A QAA v vo. m mom a mac ~ OAo- on»- AA AA OAA mam m. ”cm - Aoo who A ppm A mm. A who A no» A new A ovo- ahw- AA AA ~vm man A- «mm A- man Ava man A ”A. u chm n v~n A vmn A mhv- mac: AA 0A 0A sch A- mmm A- mm “mm omo hhh A mom ~ ohm mmo A on- vav- 0A a AAA - «A. A- Av. A- omA - AAA AA NAA A cam A Ne. An. mnv- v..- a a ma won A- non A- «MA - qu vmm moA A vo ~ ms. vhv Ann: omn- m n can mom - Ava - ow - Nam unA AHN A «an A mom oo~ «AM. von- 5 o NBA hNA A- mmo A- ANA Am mAA awn - cam A NBA awn hmn- FFN- o m AAA - AoA A- voA A- mnm - moA «A - AoA A .mv A ”An OAn own- vmm- m A mm~ - AAA A- .0A A- ADA - Ah AA - ,A- A «mm A «an mAv «An- 0AA- v m on ovm HI NmN HI NmH om mru ..L‘ 4 ~03 A «no mHO OHM.- tht n m pvv - won A- mom A. BAN - MA «an - ,Aa can A Aom mp. ovv- nAv- N A ”AA - mom A- oAm A- -- -- --- -.- 4 www A mhm mam can: nhm- A _ - A ..3, . . . . ,mu -,-A-Am~A AnmvooAuAmmu An - Amm-vmv AmmmA v-uvu AmmmA mm-AuNA A.AV.AAAV AA~V+AmAA AWWWOOAuAANV Aomv AmeooAquAv AmA. $2 $3 33 422-453 12:3,: Aawvnflmu. .oz .mmwalu Ou mmqum nquum vvanoAAo> muuomxm A-Aeh upouk» 0a mucos>xn m¢UAum anodum anodum noodum .oz 9. (nuou cA wamom, ax AcauAJL uvcuo wo mo EAucano nu -, m;_u cmAmhom haxmmoa A4 acouuso hw\mwm~ u< acouusu mJHu-AA-m .Ao .AoAA/mcmm wfi map A: uo >u.AunQA~U -. uAuAuwQ A3. .3050ch mmvcuno mm . msoco we MAMOQLA mmmA uchmo< Huuflmuo mo )OmucH uoz anewuouwuuoad m .OflscHuCOUIu . him m4; APPENDIX G DATA USED IN ESTIMATING THE BEHAVIOR OF DIRECT FOREIGN INVESTMENTS 343 344 .m xflwcmmmd .vlm magma “gm mom .mwSmmfi gamuuso .moflumflumum HMflocmnHm HMGOflumcumch "Amy Mom .Amnma hundunmmv hm 6cm Amhma HmQEm>OZV mm .mowemaoum musucshcou "u% can AHV mom Amounom mm.o «.OH H.mma m.mNH oom mnma mm.o m-HH H.HNH o.oma wva Hhma hm.a m.m m.Hm m.mHH mma onma mm.H o.m m.mma n.NHH mma mmma vm.m m.m w.vn v.moa Hm mmma nm.m m.v m.Hh m.moa on hmma nv.m H.m H.Oh w.moa vb mama vm.m h.~ m.mm m.~oa on mmma mv.h m.m m.nm m.ooa mm vmma va.v m.H om ooa om mmma um 3% AA 5 A: wumm mmcmnoxm mam Hmmm mo ooaxAN\Hv xmwcH moflnm mcoflaafle mm: Hmmm Hafioflmmo nuzouu mo mumm mucmEumm>cH mammmaonz ucmuusu CH may CH Amcmflm mmfluficdunommo cmflmuom .m.D mucmEumm>cH 0c zuflzv mmcmnu ufimoum uumuflo mo cmflmuom uomuwa mmmucmonmm mAnucoz mo mmmum>¢ Hmsaad MOM >xonm msam> HMHHOQ ucmumcou .mucmeumm>cH cmflmuom uomufla mo uofl>mzmm mzu mcaumeflumm :H Ummo mumoll.ano mqmda APPENDIX H EVIDENCE OF GREATER EFFICIENCY AFTER MINIDEVALUATIONS 345 .d' EVIDENCE OF GREATER EFFICIENCY AFTER MINIDEVALUATIONS An examination of the residual factor in economic growth can give an indication as to whether or not the economy was more efficient in the use of productive factors after 1968, following the introduction of mini- devaluations. The residual factor in economic growth is the growth of output that cannot be accounted for by the growth of labor and capital. Assuming that the economy can be represented by a constant return to scale production function and also assuming competitive factor pricing, the residual (R) can be written as where 9 is the rate of growth of real GDP, nk is the capital share in national income, n is the labor share, L R is the rate of growth in the capital stock, and t is the rate of growth of the labor force. It also may be written as R=y-Ck-CL, where Ck is the contribution of capital growth and CL is that of labor growth. Using the data for Ck and CL 346 347 estimated by Carlos G. Langoni,l it is clearly seen in Table H-l that the residuals for the period after 1968 are much greater than those for the period 1962-1967.2 The average residual was about 5.0 percent from 1968 to 1972 as compared to only 0.795 percent during the previous five years. Therefore, it may be asserted that the economy became substantially more efficient after the introduction of minidevaluations. Carlos G. Langoni, "As Fontes do Crescimento Economico Brasileiro," Tables 1 and 10. 2The high residuals in the years 1960-1961 reflect the last stage of easy import substituting industrializa- tion. 348 TABLE H-l.--The Productivity Residual in Brazilian Economic Growth. Productivity Years R = y - Ck - CL Residual 1960 R = 9.7 - 1.833 = 1.7 = 6.167 1961 R = 10 3 - 1.677 - 1.6 = 7.023 1962 R = 5.3 - 1.714 - 1.6 = 1.986 1963 R = 1 5 - 1.570 - 1.6 = -1.670 1964 R = 2.9 - 1.611 - 1.6 = - .311 1965 R = 2.7 - 1.432 - 1.6 = - .332 1966 R = 5.1 - 1.902 - 1.6 = 2.698 1967 R = 4.8 - 1.830 - 1.6 = 1.390 1968 R = 8.4 - 2.286 - 1.6 = 4.514 1969 R = 9.0 - 2.665 - 1.6 = 6.335 1970 R = 9.5 - N.A. - 1.6 R 4.2* 1971 R = 11.3 - N.A. - 1.6 5 6.0* 1972 R = 10.4 - N.A. - 1.6 b 5.1* Source: For Ck and CL, Carlos Geraldo Langoni, "As Fontes do Crescimento Economico no Brasil," Estudos Economicos, 2, No. 4 (1972), 13 and 23. For 9 , Cofiifintura Economica, 26 (November 1972) and 25 (February 1973). * Assuming Ck = 3.7. BIBLIOGRAPHY Alejandro, Carlos Diaz. Exchange-Rate Devaluation in a Semi-Industrialized Country: The Experience of Argentina, 1955-1961. Cambridge, Mass.: The M.I.T. Press, 1968, p. 191. Alejandro, Carlos Diaz. "Stop-Go Cycles and Inflation During the Portwar Period." In Essays on the Economic History of the Argentine Republic. New Haven and London: Yale University Press, 1970, PP. 367-89. Allen, R. G. D. Macro-Economic Theory, A Mathematical Treatment. New York: Macmillan, St. MartifiTs Press, 1968. Almonacid, Ruben Dario. "O Exeito da Taxa Cambial Sabre o Produto." Estudos Economicos, 2 (October 1972), 155-70. Bacha, Edmar and Taylor, Lance. "Foreign Exchange Shadow Prices: A Critical Review of Current Theories." Quarterlngournal of Economics, 85 (May 1971), 197-224. Balassa, Bela and Schydlowsky, Daniel M. "Effective Tariffs, Domestic Cost of Foreign Exchange and the Equilibrium Exchange Rate." Journal of Political Economy, 76 (May-June 19685, 356-59. Banco Central do Brasil. Relatério 1967-1971. Banco do Brasil S.A. Relatério, Exercicio de 1971. Banco do Brasil, S.A. Brasil, Exportacao 1972. CACEX- NUCEX. Banco do Brasil, Brasil-Comércio Exterior—-Foreign Trade 1971. Bergsman, Joel. Brazil Industrialization and Trade Policies. Oxford: OECD, Oxford University Press, 1970. 349 350 Bergsman, Joel and Candal, Arthur. "Industrialization: Past Success and Future Problems." In The Economy of Brazil. Edited by H. S. ElligT Berkeley: University of California Press, 1969, p. 33. Boletim do Comércio Exterior. Boletim, Banco Central do Brasil. Bracher, Fernao C. B. "Sistema Cambial de Taxa Flexivel." O Estado de Sao Paulo, 24 (November 1968), 71. Branson, T. H. and Willet, T. D. "Policy Toward Short-Term Capital Movements. Some Implications of the Port- folio Approach." Paper presented at the con- ference on International Mobility and Movement of Capital, sponsored by The International Bureau of Economic Research, January, 1970. Bruno, Michael. "Domestic Resource Costs and Effective Protection." Journal of Political Economy, 80 (January-February 1972), 16-33. Cavalcanti, Antonio Nilson Quezado and Cracco, Ettiene. "Os Incentivos e as Exportacoes de Manufaturados; Anélise e Sugestao." Revista de Administrapao de Emprésas, 12 (January-March 1972), 63-9. Chenery, Hollis B. "Comparative Advantage and Development Policy." American Economic Review, 51 (March 1961), 18-51. Chow, G. C. "Tests of Equality Between Sets of Coefficients in Two Linear Regressions." Econometrica, 28 (1960), 591-605. Christoffersen, Leif. "Taxas de juros e a Estrutura de um Sistema de Bancos Comerciais em Condicoes Inflacionarias." Revista Brasileira de Economia, 23 (June 1969). Clement, M. O.; Pfister,Richard L.; and Rothwell, Kenneth J. Theoretical Issues in International Economics. Boston: Houghton, Mifflin Co., 1967. Conjuntura Economica. Delfim, Netto A.; Pastore, A. C.; Cipollari, P.; and Carvalho, E. P. Alguns Aspectos da Inflacao Brasileira. Sao Paulo: ANPES, 1935. 351 Diz, Adolfo C. "Money and Prices in Argentina, 1935-1962." Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, University of Chicago, 1966. Doellinger, Carlos Von. "Exportacoes brasileiras: diagnostico e perspectivas." Pesquisa e Planejamento (June 1971), 83-140. Doellinger, Carlos Von. "Capitais Externos, Balanco de Pagamentos e Crescimento Econdmico." Internal Document, IPEA, 1972. Doellinger, Carlos Von; Faria, H. B. B.; Pereira, J. E. C.; and Horta, M. H. T. T. Exportacoes denamicas brasileiras. Rio de Janeiro: 1971, IPEA. Donges, Juergen B. Brazil's Trotting Peg, A New Approach to Greater Exchange.Rate Flexibility in Less DevelOped Countries. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, August, 1971. Fajnzylber, Fernando. Sistema Industrial e Exportagao de Manufaturados. Anélise da Experiéncia Brasileira. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA/INPES, 1971. Federal Reserve Bulletin. Fisher, F. M. "Tests of Equality Between Sets of Coeffi- cients in Two Linear Repressions: An Expository Note." Econometrica, 38 (1970), 361-66. Fishlow, Albert. "Brazilian Size Distribution of Income." American Economic Review, 62 (May 1972). Friedman, M. "The Case for Flexible Exchange;Rates." In Essays in Positive Economics. Edited by M. Friedman. Chicago: UnIVersity of Chicago Press, 1953, pp. 157-203. Furtado, Celso. Obstacles to Development in Latin America. Translated by Charles Ekker. Garden City, New York: Andros Books, 1970. Gudin, E. "The Chief Characteristics of the Postwar Economic Development of Brazil." In The Economy of Brazil. Edited by Howard Ellis. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1969. 3S2 Halm, George N. Toward Limited Flexibility of Exchange Rates. Princeton: International Finance Sec- tion, Department of Economics, Princeton Univer— sity, 1969. Halm, George N., ed. Approaches to Greater Flexibility of Exchange Rates: The Burgenstock Papers. Arranged by C. Fred Bergsten, George N. Halm, Fritz Machlup and Robert V. Roosa. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1970. Harberger, Arnold C. "The Dynamics of Inflation in Chile." In Measurement in Economics: Studies in Mathe- matical Economics and Econometrics in Memory of Yettuda Grunfeld. Edited by Carl Christ et a1. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1963. Heller, R. and Kreinin, M. "Adjustment Costs, Optimal Currency Areas, and International Reserves." Hesse, Herman. "Promotion of Manufactured Exports as Development Strategy of Semi-Industrialized Countries: The Brazilian Case." Weltwirts- chaftliches Archiv., Review of World Economics, I08, No. 2 (1972?, 234-55. Hoffman, Rodolfo and Duarte, Joao Carlos. "A Distribuicao de Renda no Brasil." Revista de Administrapao de Emprésas, 12 (April-June 1972). International Financial Statistics. Johnson, Harry G. "The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates, 1969." In V. K. and Floating Exchanges. Edited by H. G. Johnson and J. E. Nash. London: The Institute of Economic Affairs, 1969. Reprinted in Halm, ed., Approaches to Greater Flexibility, pp. 91-111. Johnston, J. Econometric Methods. 2nd Ed. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1972. Kafka, Alexander. "The Brazilian Exchange Auction System." Review of Economics and Statistics, 38 (August 1956), 308-22. Kenen, Peter B. "The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: An Eclectic View." In Monetapy Problems of the International Economy: Papers and Discussions. Edited by Robert A. Mundell and Alexander Snoboda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1969)- PP. 41-60. 353 Kmenta, Jan. Elements of Econometrics. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1971. Koyck, L. M. Distributed Lags and Investment Anal sis. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co., I954. Kreinin, Mordechai E. International Economics: A Policy A roach. New York: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich, Inc., I971. Kreinin, Mordechai E. Alternative Commercial Policies-— ~ Their Effect on the American Economy. East Lansing: Michigan State University, 1967. Langoni, Carlos G. "As Fontes de Crescimento Economico Brasiliero." Estudos Econ6micos, 2: NO- 4 (1972)- 3-34. Langoni, Carlos G. "Distribuicao de Renda e Desenvolvimento Economico do Brasil." Estudos Econémicos, 2 (October 1972). Lira, Paulo H. Pereira. "Cruzeiro 0 Pre o Exato da Moeda." Revista Econamica, Jornal do Brasil, 26 (March 1971), 32. Lira Paulo H. Pereira. "Endividamento Externo e Desenvolvimento." Revista Economica, Jornal do Brasil, 31 (March 1972), I20. Lira, Paulo H. Pereira. "Politica de Endividamento externo." Unpublished Conference Paper Delivered to the Superior War College, July 1972. McKinnon, Ronald I. "Optimum Currency Areas." American Economic Review, 53 (September 1963), 717-25. McKinnon, Ronald I. Monetapy Theory and Controlled Flexibility in the Foreign Exchanges. Essays in International Finance, No. 84. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1971, pp. 21-3. Mundell, Robert A. "Flexible Exchange Rate and Employment Policy." Canadian qurnal of Economics‘and Political Science, 27 (November 1961), 509-17. Mundell, Robert A. "The Monetary Dynamics of International Adjustment Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84 (May 1960?, 227-57. Mundell, Robert A. International Economics. New York: The Macmillan Company, 1968. 354 Mundell, Robert A. "A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas." American Economic Review, 50 (September 1961), 657-65. Rhomberg, R. Rudolf. "Canada's Foreign Exchange Market: A Quarterly Model." International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 7 (April 1960), 439-56. Robinson, Sherman. "Sources of Growth in Less Developed Countries." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85, No. 3 (August 1971), 391-408. Selowsky, Marcelo. "On the Measurement of Education's Contribution to Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 83 (August 1969Y7’449-63. Simonsen, Mario H. Inflagéo, Gradpalismo x Tratamento de Choque. Rio: APEC, 1970. Simonsen, Mario H. Brasil 2002. APEC Editora, Rio de Janeiro: 1972. Sohmen, Egon. International Monetary Problems and the Foreign Exchanges. Princeton N. J.: Inter- national Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University, 1963. Sohmen, Egon. Flexible Exchange Rates: Theory and Controversy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1961. Suplicy, Eduardo M. "Graphic Presentation of a Macro- economic Model: The Inflationary Spiral." Rev1sta Brasileira de Economia, 24 (Oct.-Dec. 1970). Tyler, William G. "As Taxas de Cambio Cadentes e a Inflacao Endemica." Revista Brasileira de Eponomia, 22 (December 1968i, 80-93. Tyler, William G. "Exchange Rate Flexibility Under Condi- tions of Endemic Inflation: A Case Study of Recent Brazilian Experiences." Unpublished Paper, U.S. AID, 1971. Tyler, William G. "Export Diversification and the Promotion of Manufactured Exports in Brazil." Mimeographed U.S. AID Study, August 1969. 355 Tyler, William G. "Fiscal Incentives for Manufactured Export Promotion: The Brazilian Case." Working Paper 72-01, Department of Economics, University of Florida. U. S. Survey of Current Business. U. S. Federal Reserve Bulletin. Wonnacott, Ronald J. and Wonnacott, Thomas H. Econometrics. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1970. "11111011111