in. . ;.:.... 4.: , .43? . r 2. . ‘ V 4 ‘ . ‘ . ‘ 3.. . $32.... a; . ‘ ‘ . . . z.-." :2. .. . a , . n . . It}, 454- .h‘lh‘ P“ ‘ , \ul . . . . ..n. 1.1.... ~ . . J». 1... yu...£ . _ ad. .4 gave». _ , .4, wuwnwfiw... . 4 . , . . 3. 7r : 6 i! 2... . ‘ . ‘ . ‘ 1 jute... a. 29.4 . . l .w .3... . _ . . ‘ . ., x. V . 59!; {Mafia . . -Ii . 3. ...r.a 21.3.17 .1 3-.. 1 . Anna. 13...: .. 2.»... a}... (A. d v ‘ _ 3,3 . is n. u! .5 pl? :1. 1‘3... 3 {a}! .. “rum“ :2 1.? :15. Fill. A? 19.1.. . ‘ 3 in «1...... 5.3'0 OI ‘8 v.1. z i! x J: at. ‘Yiv. t. . an. 5?: ‘ :3. .1 fimmflfld . ‘ . (Ixtrutiw {1|s :Uhh!:\.ia£ {SW}! .2. ‘ .1 (f . 91 A... .l.xn\¥€}\.31‘.ns 3. six“? 0|}.n; l.‘p£i.S.|A-1§ 53? \5’\ .2 El! i2”... ’ |\i‘\i\~'fii\ \\\\\‘\\T\\\x\i\i [jam l; i. Tu i \| 31293 \\ This is to certify that the dissertation entitled DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF CURRENCY DEVALUATION ON HOUSEHOLDS TN RWANDA: AN APPLICATION OF WILLINGNESS-TO-PAY WELFARE MEASURES presented by Nicholas W. Minot has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Agricultural Economics flm/ 1% Major-‘Bro‘ressor Date—Mewz 0-12771 MS U i: an Affirmative Action/Eq ual Opportunity Institution — u—t ‘t‘i’k LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN BOX to romovo this checkout from your rocord. TO AVOID FINES roturn on or bdoro doto duo. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE JUL 3 1 M8 _{ . v_———_—- MSU In An Afflrmotlvo Action/Equal Opportunity Institution Wanna-c1 DISTRIBUTIONAL EFFECTS OF CURRENCY DEVALUATION ON HOUSEHOLDS IN RWANDA: AN APPLICATION OF WILLINGNESS-TO-PAY WELFARE MEASURES BY Nicholas w. Minot A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1992 ABSTRACT Distributional Effects of Currency Devaluation on Households in Rwanda: An Application of Willingness-To-Pay Welfare Measures BY Nicholas W. Minot Currency devaluation is a controversial policy measure in develop- ing countries. One of the most common criticisms is that devaluation causes disproportionate suffering among the poor. This study investi- gates theléggggggutional impact of price changes associated with devalu- ation in Rwanda. It uses a simpiifiEdflhouseholdefirm model based on household budget data and both hypothetical and historical prices to simulate the effect of devaluation on demand, real income, and nutrition. l/,l\ Two aspects of the research approach deserve note. First,<;3ther; using the standard method of simulating the impact on a handful of "archetypal" households, this study approximates the effect of price changes on each household in the sample, allowing the results to be aggregated to any desired sub-group of the population Second, in addition to the standard measures of welfare impact iconsumer surplus and the Laspeyres price index), the two "willingness-to-pay" measures are calculated using the method suggested by Vartia (1983). The results indicate that the ..{£.‘...g§..“.....iated with devalu- ation have a proportionately greater negative impact on the real income of urban and high-income households than on rural and low—income house— holds, principally because the latter are insulated from all price changes by the importance of home production. These results highlight the risks of simple generalizations about the distributional impact of devaluation. ii Cbpynghtby NICHOLAS WILLIAM MINOT 1992 DEDICATION I dedicate this work to Lisa, my wife, colleague, and friend iii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS In the course of my graduate program, I have benefited greatly from the support and encouragement of a wide range of people. First and foremost, I would like to thank Dr. Donald Mead, my thesis advisor, and Dr. Michael Weber, my major professor. Dr. Mead has been a constant source of professional guidance and moral support, both in Rwanda where he was my research supervisor (and neighbor) for two years and back at Michigan State University where he helped me develop the dissertation topic. In addition, he has inspired me by his ability to combine tech- nical skills as an economist with a personal commitment to "making a difference." Dr. Weber has provided valuable support ever since my first con- tact with Michigan State University in 1982. Dr. Weber has been instru- mental in arranging the financial and material resources necessary for my research. Even more importantly, he has served a valuable role through his skill at asking the right questions and by continually refo- cusing my attention on the policy—relevance of the results. I have also benefited from the other members of my thesis and guidance committes. Dr. Tom Reardon provided valuable comments on vari- ous aspects of the dissertation, occasionally recharging my interest in the topic. The econometric modelling was ably guided by Dr. Peter Schmidt, who was always available for my questions. Dr. James Shaffer was a source of healthy skepticism about all my neoclassical preconcep- tions. And Dr. Carl Eicher, like Dr. Weber, has supported my studies and professional development in various ways over the past decade. I would also like to thank a number of collegues from my time in Rwanda. Bonaventure Niyibizi, my fellow-analyst and good friend at the Ministry of Planning, almost single—handedly made my stay in Rwanda enjoyable. Dr. Francois Kanimba, then the Director General of Planning, iv originally suggested the dissertation topic. Théodomir Muligo, Director of Surveys at the Ministry, protected me from bureacratic "turf bat- tles," allowing me to carry out the research. Dr. Greg Lassiter facili- tated my continuing involvement in the ENBC analysis on a short-term basis after 1988. And Jim Otto, computer programmer par excellance, got the ENBC data processing off the ground in 1985-86 with his hard work and sense of humor. The ENBC analysis was also assisted by computer programer Nsengim- ana Elie, statisticians Philip Rees and Paul-Henri Wirrankoski, demogra- pher Michel Simonet, and Drs. Victor Smith and James Ansoanuur, both economists. The data cleaning was facilitated by the cooperation of Albert Munyankumburwa and his crew of coding agents. Even Christophe Muller helped make my experience at the Ministry of Planning "memora- ble." My two-year contract in Rwanda was funded by the Employment and Enterprise Policy Analysis project, while the short-term consultancies and my research assistantship at Michigan State University were paid for by the Agricultural Survey and Policy Analysis Project. Both projects were funded by the United States Agency for International Development, and thus, ultimately, by the U.S. taxpayers. Most of all, I would like to express my deep gratitude to my wife, Lisa Daniels, who somehow managed to make the last three years of gradu- ate school actually enjoyable. Perhaps I could have done it without her unwavering support and good humor, but it would not have been nearly as much fun! \J 4. TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER ONE: INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Objectives of the study . . . . . . . . . . Organization of the study . . . . . . . . . CHAPTER TWO: BACKGROUND ON RWANDA . . . . . . . . 2.1 Description of Rwanda . . . . . . 2.1.1 Geography and climate . . 2.1.2 People and history . . . . 2.1.3 Structure of the economy . Background of the crisis . . . . 2.2.1 Economic policy . . . . . 2.2.2 External sector . . . . . Structural adjustment program . . 2.3.1 Trade and exchange rate policy 2.3.2 Fiscal and monetary policy . . 2.3.3 Structural reforms . . . . . . CHAPTER THREE: REVIEW OF LITERATURE . . . . . . . 3.1 3.2. 3.3 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Impact of currency devaluation . . . . . 3.2.1 Theory of devaluation . . . . . Empirical studies of devaluation . s of household behavior . . . . . . Theory of consumer demand . . . . Functional form of demand equations Issues in the estimation of consumer Household-firm models . . . . . . . Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . re effects of price and income changes Producer surplus . . . . . . . . . Consumer surplus . . . . . . . . . U N O N oe wwuwwgwwuwwz O O O O O O O O O O bebhpwwuuwwa cocoop-hooooo MDWNHWMkUNl-‘H Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . CHAPTER FOUR: RESEARCH METHODS . . . . . . ¥\4.1. -}4.2. Overview of research approach . Household as consumer . . . . . . . 4.3.1 Assumptions about preferences . 4. 3. 2 Functional form of demand equations 3.3 Estimation of demand . . . . . . . .4 Derivation of elasticities of demand Data sources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2.1 Survey sample . . . . . . . . . 4. 2. 2 Data collection methods . . . . . . 4. 2. 3 Data processing methods . . . . . . 5 ehold as producer . . . . . . . . . . . 1 Effect of prices and income . . . . 2 Supply response of agriculture . . . vi 0 c Q. o o o o o 0 Additional issues in demand estimation Compensating variation and equivalent varia Methods of estimating willingness to pay 0 c (To 0 o c o P o O o o o o o o TABLE or CONTENTS (cont.) 4.5. Price changes associated with devaluation . . . . . . 4.5.1 Historical price data . . . . . . . . . . . . 4 5 2 Hypothetical prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.6 Effect of price changes 4 6.1 Effect of price changes on demand . . . . . . 4 6 2 Effect of price changes on nutrition . . . . 4.6.3 Effect of price changes on household welfare \/'5 CHAPTER FIVE: HOUSEHOLD BUDGET PATTERNS IN RWANDA . . . . . ‘1 5.1 Characteristics of Rwandan households . . . . . . . . ./5.2 Composition of household income . . . . . . . . . . 5.2.1 Definition of net income . . . . . . 5.2.2 Proportion of income from different activities 5.2.3 Proportion of households by primary occupation 5.2.4 Proportion of households involved in different activities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . \/5.3. Composition of household expenditure . . . . . . . . 5.3.1 Definition of expenditure . . . . . . . . . . 5.3.2 Average expenditure and size-distribution . . 5.3.3 Expenditure for different types of households 5.3. 4 Composition of expenditure . . . . . . . . . . 5.4 Agricultural production in the rural sector . . . . 5.4.1 Land . . . . 5.4.2 Purchased inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.4.3 Agricultural production and marketing . . . . 5.5 Effect of price changes on households . . . . . . . . 5.5.1 Participation in the market . . . . . . . . . 5.5.2 Net position in agricultural commodities 5.5.3 Tradeable component of expenditure and income 5.5.4 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 CHAPTER SIX: MODEL OF HOUSEHOLD DEMAND . . . . . . . . . . 6.1 Selection of the appropriate model . . . . . . . . 6.1.1 Treatment of rural and urban samples . . . . . 6.1.2 Commodity Categories . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.1.3 Estimation method: OLS vs SUR . . . . . . . 6.2 Unrestricted SUR model of rural demand . . . . . . . 6.2.1 Overall goodness-of-fit and significance . . 6.2.2 Effect of total expenditure . . . . . . . . 6. 2. 3 Effect of household composition . . . . . . . 6. 2. 4 Effect of prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.3 SUR model of rural demand with symmetry imposed . 6.4 Unrestricted SUR model of urban demand . . . . . . . 6.4.1 Overall goodness—of—fit and significance . . . 6.4.2 Effect of total expenditure . . . . . . . . 6.4.3 Effect of household composition . . . . . . . 6.4.4 Effect of prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.5 SUR model of urban demand with symmetry imposed . . . 6.6 Effect of zero-expenditures on the model . . . . . . 6.7 Measurement error and quality effects . . . . . . . vii TABLE OF CONTENTS (cont.) CHAPTER SEVEN: IMPACT OF CURRENCY DEVALUATION . . . . . . . 193 7.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193 7.2 Effects of hypothetical currency devaluation: base scenario . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194 7.2.1 Assumptions used in base scenario . . . . . . 7. 2. 2 Aggregate demand and caloric intake . . . . . 197 7. L 3 Distributional effects of the hypothetical devaluation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 202 7.3 Effects of historical prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . 210 7.3.1 General price trends over 1989-90 . . . . . . . 211 7.3.2 Prices used in the simulation . . . . . . . . . 214 7.3.3 Aggregate demand and caloric intake . . . . . . 216 7.3.4 Distributional effects of historical price changes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 221 .4 Alternative assumptions about wage rates . . . . . . . 224 5 Alternative assumptions about agricultural supply response O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 225 .6 Demand response assumption . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 231 .7 Comparison of welfare measures . . . . . . . . . . . . 232 .8 Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 237 CHAPTER EIGHT: CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS . . . . . 239 v/8.1 Summary of results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 239 ~L8.1.1 Income and expenditure patterns . . . . . . . 8.1.2 Model of consumer demand . . . . . . . . . . . . 243 8.1.3 Impact of price changes associated with devaluation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 245 8.2 Implications for policy . . . . . . 247 8.2.1 Magnitude of the impact of devaluation . . . . . 247 8. 2. 2 Alleviation of the impact of devaluation . . . . 248 8.3 Implications for research methods . . . . . . . . . . 250 8.3.1 Advantages of micro-simulation . . . . . . . . 250 8. 3. 2 Factors affecting the impact of devaluation . . 251 8.3.3 Alternative welfare measures . . . . fx8.4 Limitations of the study and suggestions for further research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 252 . . . . . . . . 253 LIST OF REFERENCES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 256 APPENDIX A: Devaluation and bean prices . . . . . . . . . 264 APPENDIX B: Adult equivalence scales . . . . . . . . . . 266 APPENDIX C: Regression coefficients and t statistics . . . . 267 viii Table 0101 t'ntn 001 pm OOOO men ¢n01mcru1mtnu1m Hr» iahawt4hap\ooaq um m-wat-‘O't"" I LUMP I I I I I I I I HHHHKOCDQO‘U‘ID m 0 for all i) 91 is the sub-utility functions for group i Weak separability may be understood in terms of "two-stage budgeting," in which the household first maximizes utility by allocating expenditure among the commodity groups, and then allocates group expenditure among the goods comprising each group. The implication in terms of the substitution matrix is that: .= 32:32.2: ‘1 “'6x 6x 0) (3-12) where q1 = the quantity of good i in group G qJ = the quantity of good j in group H Pea = a constant A common application of this assumption is the case in which only food expenditure data are available. By assuming weak separability between food and non-food, the composition of the food budget can be analyzed without reference to non-food spending patterns. A much more restrictive assumption is strong (or additive) separability. Under this assumption, the direct utility function has the following structure: u=f[g1(q1...q,) +gz(qa.1...qb) + +gn(qz...qN)] (3-13) where u = utility f is a function (f1 > 0 for all i) 91 is the sub-utility function for group i lBecause it is expressed as a monotonic function of the sum of the sub- latilities, even a utility function in which the sub-utility functions Eire multiplied together would fit into this definition. One implication 33 of strong separability is that the substitution matrix has the following restriction: (3-14) where qi = the quantity of good i in group G q3 = the quantity of good j in group H u = a constant This equation differs from that corresponding to weak separability in that the constant, p, does not vary among pairs of commodity groups. An even more important implication of strong (or additive) separability is that there is a fixed relationship between the expenditure elasticity and the price elasticity, as first noted by Frisch (1959). This explains the popularity of strong separability in the context of empirical work. Nonetheless, Deaton and Meulbauer (1980a: 139) caution that the powerful results come at the cost of strong, often unrealistic, restrictions on preferences. Aggregation over consumers: The next issue is concerns aggregation of demand across consumers. In particular, under what conditions can aggregate consumer behavior be described as if it were the result of decisions made by a utility-maximizing representative consumer? The simplest case is that of exact linear aggregation, in which the average demand across consumers is a function of prices and the average level of total expenditure. It is possible to show that this property can only exist if 1) the demand is a linear function of total expenditure and 2) the marginal propensities to consume a given good are the same across consumers. Although aggregate demand in such a model is consistent with utility maximization, the restrictions on preferences are quite strong and unrealistic (Deaton and Muelbauer, 1980a). Exact non-linear aggregation requires that average demand across consumers be a function of prices and some representative level of total expenditure. This representative level of expenditure could be a 34 function of prices and the distribution of expenditure. It turns out that this implies that, for a given household, the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) of each good varies linearly with the MPC of other goods. A special case of exact non-linear aggregation occurs when the representative expenditure level is independent of price. Under these conditions, called Price Independent Generalized Linearity (PIGL), the representative expenditure function and the demand function take the following forms: e(U.p) = [(1-u) [a1(p)]' + uta,(p)1¢]“‘ (3-15) wi = bu-(p) + bu(p)(%‘)" (3-16) where k and a are parameters u is utility a1(p) and b1(p) are functions of prices As a approaches zero, the exponents become logarithms and the form is thus known as PIGLOG. The expenditure and demand functions are as follows: e(U.p) = (1-U) log[d1(p)] + u log[d2(p)] (3-17) kg = f1(p) + f, (p) 1096(5) (3-18) where d1(p) and fi(p) are functions of prices u is utility In summary, the advantage of exact aggregation is that it simplifies the calculation of aggregate responses to changes in income or prices. Exact aggregations, however, imposes some restrictions on the shape of the demand curves. The decision whether to use a model characterized by exact aggregation must depend on 1) the degree to which the restrictions of exact aggregation are violated by the data and 2) the additional calculation costs involved in using models that do not have exact aggregation. 35 3.3.2 Eppgpippgl form of demand ggpgpigpg Economic theory does not specify the functional form of the demand equations. Early studies, such as Allen and Bowley (1935), estimated demand assuming a linear relationship between demand for a given commodity and total expenditure. Prais and Houthaker (1955) compare a variety of functional forms, suggesting that the choice among them be based on goodness-of-fit. The double-logarithmic form has been used often because the estimated parameters are directly interpreted as elasticities. This procedure is acceptable when only one or a small number of commodities is being estimated, but is inappropriate for estimating a complete system because the equations do not satisfy the properties of demand. For example, the double-log form does not even satisfy adding up. This has led to the development of functional forms which are appropriate for a system of demand equations. Systems of dgmgnd egpations: The linear expenditure system (LES), developed by Stone (1954), was the first demand system to satisfy all the general properties of demand: adding-up, homogeneity, symmetry, and negativity. The LES is highly restrictive, however, prohibiting inferior goods and complements. Furthermore, it is based on an additive utility function, which imposes a relationship between expenditure and price elasticities. In spite of these restrictions (or perhaps because of the advantages they yield), the LES has been a Vfrequent choice of researchers (see for example Lluch, Powell, and Williams, 1977). The Rotterdam model is similar to the LES, but instead of imposing homogeneity and symmetry algebraically, it allows them to be imposed (and thus tested) statistically. Most empirical studies have rejected symmetry and homogeneity, but it is not clear if this is a rejection of the consistency of consumer behavior or some misspecification of the demand model (Deaton and Muelbauer, 1980a). 36 In the 1970s, duality theory suggested the possibility of deriving new "flexible" demand functions from direct utility functions, indirect utility functions, and expenditure functions. For example, using an indirect utility function in the form of the transcendental logarithmic function, the ”indirect translog" demand system can be derived using Roy’s Identity. The ”direct translog" system is similarly derived from a translog direct utility function. However, these systems are non- linear in the parameters and are thus difficult to estimate (Deaton and Muelbauer, 1980a and Phlips, 1983). Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS): The flexible demand function which has been most widely used in recent years is the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS), proposed by Deaton and Muelbauer (1980b). It is based on an expenditure function in the PIGLOG class, permitting exact aggregation over consumers. By applying Shephard's Lemma to the expenditure function, the following demand function is obtained: "1 = [310 + Billogfi-fi) + Z$¢xijlog 1) over some range of expenditure and a "necessity" or "inferior" (e < 1) over another range. This property is particularly important when the system includes a large number of disaggregated commodities. In addition, the quadratic version retains most of the advantages of the AIDS: it is linear in the parameters when Stone's index is used, adding-up is imposed automatical- ly when estimated with OLS, and homogeneity and symmetry can be imposed and/or tested using linear restrictions on the parameters. 38 The restrictions necessary to impose adding-up if the model is not estimated with OLS are as follows: 2:916 = 0' $911 = 0' $91: = 0, 22“” = 0 (3-22) The restrictions to impose homogeneity and symmetry are the same as those for the AIDS: I 0 gen” - (homogeneity) (3-23) “11 = a” (symmetry) Swamy and Binswanger (1983) find the coefficient on the quadratic term to be statistically significant in a model of food demand in India. Deaton and Case (1988) use the quadratic version of the AIDS in estimat- ing demand in Indonesia and Sri Lanka. Similarly, Thomas, Strauss, and Barbosa (1989) find the quadratic term significant for 15 of 20 products in a demand model for Brazil. And in preliminary estimates of demand from the Rwandan data, the quadratic terms were significant for many budget categories, particularly in the urban areas (Ministere du Plan, 1988 and 1991). 3.3.3 Issues in the estimation of consumer demand The simplest approach to estimating demand equations is to use single-equation ordinary least squares (OLS). According to the Gauss-Markov theorem, OLS yields the "best" (least variance) linear unbiased estimates of the true parameters under conditions of classical linear regression. These conditions are described in terms of the le vector of error terms (6) and the ka matrix of independent variables (X): 1) E(e) = 0 2) E(ee’) a 02 IN 3) x is of rank k (the number of variables) where km%naaaflga+e (M, 11 pi: Y1: Y1: Y1: 3‘11. = budget share of good i x = total expenditure of the household = Stone's index, defined by ln(P) = 2 W1 109(p1) price of good j where there are 9 goods gf = number of food equations in system zk = household characteristic k B y a = estimated parameters '0 LA. II The dimensions of these matrices can be described in terms of the number of observations (N), the number of food categories in the system (g5), and the number of independent variables (k¢=g£+6)1. The first set of brackets represents the independent variables, where each element is an le vector except p which is an ngt matrix. The second set of brackets 1. In the rural model, N=270, gf=17, and kf=23, while in the urban model, N=297, g£=21, and kf=27. 76 contains the coefficients, each element being a scalar except for a which is a gtxl vector. The non-food demand equations can be expressed in a similar way except that prices are omitted from the independent variables: “’1 = 910 "’ pnln(%) + Bu{ln(%)]2 * £271ka + e1 = [1 ln(%) [ln(—:)]2 Z1 Z2 Z3] '90; + e1. (4-4) 911 9:1 Yu Va: .731. where the notation is the same as in equation (4-3). Each element in the first set of brackets is an le vector, while those in the second set are scalars. The number of estimated parameters in the non-food equations, kn, is six. The independent variables can be combined into one ka matrix called X, while the parameters can be represented by a kxl vector called B1 (k=k£ for food equations and k=kn in the non-food equations). The demand equation can be expressed as follows: The ordinary least squares (OLS) estimate of Bi can be written as: B, = (X'X)'1x'w, (4-6) Ordinary least squares provides the best unbiased linear estimate under the classical regression assumptions discussed in section 3.3.3. However, single-equation OLS estimation does not allow cross-equation restrictions or hypothesis tests. Furthermore, it is not efficient if 77 the error terms are correlated across equations. In this case, we need to use seemingly unrelated regression (SUR). Seemingly unrelated regression: The seemingly unrelated regression model combines g equations into one regression model in order to use information about 1) cross-equation correlation of the error terms or 2) cross-equation restrictions on the parameters. The vari- ables and coefficients are assembled as follows: W1 ’}(1 o . 01 ’3] "e11 :5 0 A; 0 B2 e2 w3 = 0 X3 B3 + e3 (4_7) wg‘ LO 0 0 XS, th‘ e94 The subscript identifies the commodity equation; for example, x1 refers to the ka matrix of independent variables for equation i. The system can be rewritten more concisely as: w = 78 + e (4'8) where t I a Ngxl vector of budget shares for g goods and N households an Ngxgk block diagonal matrix with an ka matrix, X1, in each block B - an gkxl vector of parameters for g goods and k variables an Ngxl vector of error terms for g goods and N households XI II (D II The standard assumptions concerning the error terms in the SUR model are that: E(e) =0 and E[ee']=2®IN (4-9) where E = a gxg matrix, each element of which represents the covariance between the error terms of equations i and j for the same household IN = an NxN identity matrix 78 In other words, the demand equation for each good has a different variance, and there is a positive covariance between equations for the same household but zero covariance between equations across households. The SUR model is estimated in two steps. First, the OLS residuals are used to estimate the 2 matrix. Specifically, each element of the 2 matrix, denoted 013, is consistently estimated by (éi'éj)/(N-k*), where 61 is an le vector of OLS residuals from equation i and k' is the average number of estimated parameters per equationl. In the second step, the estimated covariance matrix is used in a feasible generalized least squares format to calculate the SUR estimate of B: B" = [ 'X' (2'1®I,,)3? ]'1 7' (2'1®I,,) 91 (4'10) The estimated covariance matrix of this estimate, designated 5, is: 6' = cov(§) = ['2' (2'1®I,,)'X' 1'1 (4‘11) The Breusch-Pagan test can be used to determine whether the cross- equation correlation of error terms is significant, which would suggest the use of the SUR model even for models without cross-equation restric- tions. This test is described at the end of section 4.3.3. Imposing symmetry: Symmetry requires that the compensat- ed effect of the price of good j on the demand for good i be equal to the compensated effect of the price of good i on demand for good j. In other words, the Hicksian substitution matrix must be symmetric. The symmetry restriction can be expressed in terms of the estimated parame— ters as follows: l. The adjustment for degrees of freedom in the denominator is not necessary for consistent estimation of an, but this adjustment may reduce bias in finite samples (see Judge et a1., 1988: 450). 79 $11 3 511 Q‘ . Q’ . —l€11 ‘ 33611 Eifiil+wj—5 321(EJJ4-w1-5) P1 “'1 P1 "’1 where 8 is the Kronecker delta (equal to 1 when i-j and 0 otherwise) and 62” is the Hicksian elasticity of demand for good i with respect to the price of good j. The expression for the Hicksian elasticity is derived in section 4.3.4. Because we are interested in the case where i is not equal to j, the Kronecker delta, 6, is equal to zero.‘ Using the definition of budget share, w1=p1q1/x, we can write the condition for symmetry as: 211;: .wj .sz(:a .wi F5 ”3 ‘pl “9 (4-13) 3.1. x¢1j+gi_l_lpq =31 x¢fl+gl__p1q1 Pj quj P1 X P1 Pij P; X After canceling terms, this expression reduces to the following: “11 3 “11 (4-14) In other words, symmetry of the matrix of price coefficients, a, is . necessary and sufficient for symmetry of the Hicksian substitution terms. Because symmetry involves restrictions involving parameters in different equations, imposing or testing symmetry must be carried out within a seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) model. A set of m linear restrictions can be written in the form RB-r=0, where R is an mxk matrix, B is the kxl matrix of parameters, and r is an mxl vector. Using the notation of equations 4-10 and 4-11, the restricted SUR estimator can be written in terms of the unrestricted SUR parameters as follows: 80 ~ 3‘ = B" + 612' (R CR')‘1(r-R§) . (4-15) Imposing symmetry on the gtxgt matrix of price coefficients, :2, involves gf(gf-l)/2 restrictions on the parameters. e s s : It is useful to test various hypoth- eses concerning the estimated coefficients. These tests are based on the assumption that the error terms are normally distributed. If the errors are not normally distributed, then the tests will hold "approxi- mately" for large samples, making use of the central limit theorem (see Judge et a1., 1988: 268-270). A group of m linear hypotheses can be expressed as RB-r=0, where R is an mxk matrix of constants, B is the kxl vector of parameters, and r is an mxl vector of constants. For single-equation linear hypotheses in the context of single-equation OLS estimation, we can use the standard F test: (RE-r)’ [R(x’X)'1R’ rims-r) /m (§’§)/Tfi-k) " F(m,N-k) (4-16) To test linear hypotheses in the SUR model of the demand system, we can use the following Wald test where the estimated covariance matrix, C, is defined in equation 4-11: (RE-IO’LRCR0‘4(R§-r) ~ x; (4‘17) This expression is only asymptotically distributed as chi squared because the covariance matrix, C, is not known and must be estimated. Judge at al. (1988) recommend an extended F-test as being somewhat more cautious than the chi-squared test. It is similar to the single- equation F-test except that the numerator includes the cross-equation covariance matrix, 2 (within C), and the denominator collapses to 1.0. 81 (R8-r)’(RCR’)'1(R§-r) m ' F(m.N9'9k') “'18) By defining the R matrix and the r vector appropriately, these tests can be used to test the single-equation null hypotheses presented in Table 4-1. Similarly, the cross-equation hypotheses in Table 4-2 can be tested in the context of the SUR model using the latter two tests. Table 4-1: Single-equation hypotheses to be tested IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-I-I-II-IIII-I-I-I-I-l Parameter re- Number of Explanation strictions - restrictions 311881280 2 Total household expenditure has no . effect on budget share of good i 812:0 1 Budget share of good i is linear in log expenditure yn=0 9 Sex of head of household has no effect on the budget share for good i mu=0 for all j 9: Prices have no effect on the bud- get share for good i Finally, in order to determine whether the SUR is appropriate for the unrestricted version of the model, we need to determine the statis- tical significance of the off-diagonal elements of 2. The Breusch-Pagan test uses the fact that, under the null hypothesis that 2 is a diagonal matrix, the following asymptotic distribution is true: 9 1-1 2 ;: 01 '2 ;-1 .11 j] The test expression is the number of observation times the sum of cross- equation correlation coefficients for each pair of equations. If the value of this expression exceeds the appropriate critical value, the null hypothesis is rejected and the SUR model should be adopted. 82 Table 4-2: Cross-equation hypotheses to be tested — Parameter re- Number of Explanation strictions restrictions 811-81220 29 Total expenditure has no effect on for all i budget share of all goods 812-0 9 Budget share is linear in log ex- for all 1 penditure for all goods 711'712'0 29 Household size has no effect on the for 311 1 budget share for all goods 711-0 9 Sex of head of household has no ef- for all i feet on budget share for all goods auao 9,2 Prices have no effect on the budget for all i,j share for all goods «13 - a“ (gf—gfl/Z Hicksian (compensated) price ef- for all i,j facts are symmetric 4.3.4 perivapion of elasticities of demand In the previous section, the methods for estimating the demand coefficients was discussed. In this section, the price and expenditure elasticities of demand are expressed in terms of these coefficients. The expenditure (income) elasticities and food price elasticities are calculated directly from estimated parameters. Non- food price elasticities are derived from the other elasticities and the assumption of additivity in preferences. Finally, the demand elastici- ties for the excluded category, "other food," are derived using the homogeneity and adding up from consumer theory. Each of these are discussed below. Elasticity of demand with respect to expenditure: The elasticity of demand with respect to income (total expenditure) can be derived by noting that: ln(wi) = 145%) = 1an + lnqi - lnx (4-20) Taking the partial of equation (4-20) with respect to ln x, we get: 83 alnwx _ alnpi + 31nq1 _ alnx alnx ’ 791m: alnx alnx = O + 61' - 1 (4'21) where 51 is the income elasticity for good i. Rearranging terms and using equation (4-2), we obtain the expression for the income elastici- ty: ei=1+Zi§=1+aigé=l+%+%1n{g) (4-22) Since the expenditure elasticity varies with the budget share and the level of total expenditure, it is normally evaluated at the mean values of these variables. at od em nd w t s ect to rices: The compensated (or Hicksian) elasticity of demand for good i with respect to the price of good j can be similarly derived. First, we take the partial of equation (4-20) with respect to p3: alnwi _ amp, + 311193 _ alnx _ 6 + - alnx alnpj - dlnpj alnpj amp, _ U - 61an (4-23) where 6 is the Kroenecker delta (equal to 1 if i=j and 0 otherwise) and 5x; is the compensated price elasticity of demand. The last term in equation (4-23) is not zero because nominal income (x) must change to compensate for the price change. Using the definition of Stene's index and the fact that real income (x/P) must remain constant: N 312(5) 62 wilnpl = P = alnx _ 1.1 = alnx . w. (4'24) Therefore, alnx _ _—alnpj ' “'1' (4-25) Solving equation (4-23) for epf and substituting in equation (4-25), we get the following: 84 . alnug 8w; 1 . . = —_ . - = — - " 4'26 5" alnpj + w] alnpj w! + "J b ( ) Using the expression for wi in equation (4-2): 611 = $1 + Wj ' 5 (4-27) 1 where 8 is the Kroenecker delta. By substituting equations (4-22) and (4-27) into the Slutsky equation, we obtain the uncompensated (Marsh- allian) own-price elasticity: . a. O 2 a“ = e“ - wje“I = T: + "1 - 1 - will + LB: +—£:’ln(%)] (4-28) a 7,1}! ' 1 ’ Bl: + 251956;) The uncompensated cross-price elasticity is derived in a similar way: _ - .. “1‘ 511 2912 x 611 - 3x1 ' W15: ‘ 7;“ ” "1 " WJ{1 * '71-‘71"(79) (4-29) 1 x Green and Alston (1990) suggest that the above method for deriving the price elasticities is incorrect. Specifically, they argue that the partial of Stone’s index with respect to p3 is not simply wJ, as shown in equation (4-24). Rather, it should also include the influence of pi on W} because the budget share is itself a function of prices. Because they view the price index and the budget share as functions of each other, Green and Alston hold that it is necessary to solve a system of simultaneous equations to derive the elasticities. This argument appears to overlook the fact that the budget share in the Stone's price index is not a function of prices, but rather a constant base-period weight for averaging the prices in the index. Just as the base-period quantities in the (arithmetic) Laspeyre index do not change, so the base-period shares in the (geometric) Stone's index are 85 constant. Indeed, a price index with variable weights would not be well-defined: if demand were sufficiently price elastic, price increases for a set of goods could reduce their budget shares enough to result in a decrease in the price index. D r ved - d e ast‘c ’e : The price elastici- ties of non-food categories are approximated by assuming strong (or additive) separability both among non-food categories and between food and non-food categories. As discussed in section 3.3.1, strong separa- bility implies the following relationship between income and price elasticities: 6,1 = 6 4) e1 - eiwju + «1) (4-30) where 613 a price elasticity of good i with respect to the price of j 6 - the Kronecker delta (equal to one if i=j and zero otherwise ¢ = -u/x £1 = income elasticity of good i wi = budget share of good i This implies a fixed relationship, which depends on the parameter m, between the income and price elasticities of each strongly separable categoryl. Setting i=j, this equation can be solved for ¢ to get the following expression: 511 * ‘1“9 = 4-31 ¢ 51(1'WIG1) ( ) Following the procedure used by Newberry (1987), we can obtain an estimate of ¢ using equation (4-31) with the estimated price and income elasticities of food. Then, this parameter and the non-food income elasticities can be combined in equation (4-30) to derive values for the non-food price elasticities under the assumption of strongly separable Preferences. 1. Additive preferences imply symmetry among separable grOLIps and price homogeneity of non-food demand equations. 86 Degived coefficients for ”other food": The coefficients for ”other food" are derived by using some of the restrictions of consumer theory: adding up and homogeneity. Adding up requires that the budget shares add up to one. Given the functional form used in this study, adding-up is ensured when the sum of each coefficient across equations is zero. Thus, the expenditure and household composition coefficients of "other food" are each defined as minus the sum of the corresponding coefficients in the g modeled equations. From these coefficients, the elasticity of demand for "other food” with respect to household expenditure can be calculated (Phlip, 1983). Homogeneity requires that a proportionate increase (or decrease) in all prices and incomes not affect the estimated budget shares. Such a change will affect equally the numerator and denominator of (x/P), leaving deflated expenditure unchanged. Thus, the only parameter restrictions necessary for homogeneity are on the price terms, “13° In particular, 9 32a” = 0 (4-32) n is necessary and sufficient for homogeneity. The price terms associated with ”other foods" are derived as follows. Starting with the homogeneity condition, we separate the coefficient representing the effect of the price of ”other foods" on the demand for good i, “an and move the summation of the remaining terms to the right side: 9% u (the subscript 0 refers to ”other foods"). The coefficients represent- ing the effect of other prices on the demand for ”other food" are obtained by assuming a limited symmetry: ¢°1=¢1°. Finally, the own-price termifor "other foods” can be obtained by again applying homogeneity: 87 9'1 coo = - a0 (4-34) Z; 1 It should be noted that the price parameters for "other food" can be derived only after all the other price parameters, both food and non- food, have been obtained. 4.3.5 dd tiona ssu s n demand estimation In Chapter 3, two sources of bias in the estimation of household demand were discussed. In this section, we describe some methods to evaluate the importance of these problems in the context of the present model., The first topic is the potential bias of using unit values in place of true prices as independent variables. The second is the effect of zero-expenditures on the estimated income and price elasticities. Qpality and measuremegp error effects: Deaton (1987a, 1988) points out that the use of unit values (the value of a transaction divided by the number of units purchased) to estimate price elasticities may generate biased estimates of price and income elasticities. As discussed in section 3.3.3, the biases are caused by quality effects and measurement error. The correction methods devised by Deaton are complex and this is not the focus of the present study. Nonetheless, it is worth investigating the magnitude of these biases in the case of the Rwandan budget data. The method suggested by Deaton relies on the assumption that true prices do not vary within the "cluster" of nearby households into which the samples of many household surveys are organized. First, measurement error effects can be detected by estimating the impact of "price" on demand within the cluster. Second, the income elasticity of quality can be estimated by regressing unit values on total expenditure within each cluster. These two tests can be implemented with the Rwandan ENBC data since it was collected using cluster sampling (there are 90 rural 88 clusters of three households each and 35 urban clusters averaging 8.5 households each). In order to look for ”price” effects on demand within the cluster, the basic food demand equation is modified by replacing the constant term with a set of dummy variables, one for each cluster in the sample: www; where G a an Nxc matrix of c dummy variables, each one representing a cluster c - the number of clusters Because we are not interested in the numerous coefficients on the dummy variables, the estimation can be simplified by subtracting the cluster means from each variable. The "within cluster” estimates are obtained by: 9,, . (X’MGX) 'lx’Mcw, (4-36) where an.‘ a kxl.vector of ”within" parameter estimates for food commodity i MG =- an NxN matrix = IN-Gm'crlc' As Deaton (1988: 420) explains: Since the model is supposedly one of spatial price variation, and the since price variation within clusters should be absent, the subtraction of the cluster means should make estimation of a price elasticity impossible. Thus, the presence of measurement error effects is tested by the significance of the price coefficients in this regression. The second test focuses on the quality effect. Since true prices are assumed constant within each cluster, any within-cluster relation- ship between unit value and the level of income (total expenditure) must be a reflection of quality differences. The following regression identifies this relationship: 89 ln(pi) - c; + (3,1111%) + fin{ln(-%)]z + $732,: + 91 (4-37) k-l where G - an Nxc matrix of dummy variables for the clusters c I the number of clusters The elasticity of quality with respect to income can be derived by taking the partial of unit values (p) with respect to income (x): alnpi B i .x 4-38 3111): 911 + 231-311%?) ( ) The null hypothesis that the expenditure coefficients are zero (Ho: 811-812-0) is equivalent to the hypothesis of no quality effects for good i. If a quality elasticity is significantly different than zero, we would expect it to be positive. 2 r -e t bs tions: For reasons discussed in section 3.3.3, a censored dependent variable model was not adopted for this study. Nonetheless, it is worth comparing the price and income elasticities derived from the standard linear regression model and those derived from a limited dependent variable model which explicitly incorporates zero-expenditures. The Tobit model, discussed in section 3.3.3, is based on the following log likelihood function: lnL = 1 F(-x’B,02) + —-llna2 - i( -x’B)2 (4-39) ’2 n[ 1 1 y; 2 202 5’1 1 where F(-) a the cumulative normal distribution function xi'B - the predicted value of the dependent variable (y) for observation i y1 = the actual value of the dependent variable The first summation is over observations where the dependent variable is zero, assuming that probability of such an observation is equal to the probability of the latent variable being negative. The second summation is over observations where the dependent variable takes a positive value and.follows the form of a standard likelihood function. 90 Because the likelihood function is non-linear, it must be maxi- mized using iterative techniques. The software package, LIMDEP, performs this non-linear maximization, generating estimates of the parameters, B, and their corresponding standard errors. . The coefficients of this model must be interpreted carefully since a change in an independent variable alters both the probability of the dependent variable being positive and the expected value conditional on its being positive. In order to derive the partial of y with respect to x3, we start with the unconditional expected value of the i"h observa- tion of dependent variable: E(y,) - F(x{fl/O)E(y1|y>0) (4-40) The first term on the right side is the probability that y is positive, while the second is the expected value of y given that it is positive. Taking the derivative with respect to an independent variable, x3, we get: arm) , 32ml y>0) amxgp/a) = F(x /0) + E(y >0) (4-41) 5x” ‘3 6x1, 1' y x11 McDonald and Moffitt (1980) show that this can be expressed in terms of estimated parameters as follows: arm) _ _ £,_ff , f, 2 ——a—xj—- ‘Fip[l 21}: E + Xijp 4' a? in f f2 f where F1 8 F(zi) a the cumulative normal density function evaluated at 21 f1 = f(zi) = the normal density function evaluated at z, 21 = xi'B/O (4-42) 4’ The standard income and price elasticities can thus be calculated by substituting this expression into the corresponding coefficients (8 and 4:} in the elasticity equations 4-22, 4-28, and 4-29. These elasticities 91 can then be compared to the results obtained using the standard linear model. 4-4 WW As discussed in section 3.3.4, household-firm models incorporate the impact of agricultural price changes on household income, and thus on consumption and marketed output. This ”profit effect" tends to dampen, or even make positive, the elasticity of food consumption with respect to own price. The elasticity of marketed output, although 'reduced, usually remains positive. 4.4.1 . c o ces 0 come In the household-firm model, prices affect the income level of the household. In section 3.4.1, it was shown that this effect can be calculated using first- or second-order approximations of producer surplus. These approximations may be considered the short- and long-term effects of prices on income, respectively, since the first- order approximation does not incorporate any change in output, as would be appropriate in the short term. There are three practical complications in using these equations. First, the concept of "quantity" is not meaningful for many income categories such as ”commerce" and "other artisanal activity." Fortu- nately, the expressions for the short- and long-run effect of prices on income can be rewritten in terms of values, the proportional change in price, and (for the long-run effect) the proportional change in output: N N AP Ax ' z: Q1Ap1 '3 z Q1p1 i (4'43) -1 1-1 pi v u 1 1 q Ap Ax-;—(q +q)Ap=;—q .1+—E——‘- (4-44) _1 2 01 11 1 .1 2 011901 q“ P01 A second issue concerns the assumptions about business expenses. In this study, we assume these costs change in the same proportion as 92 revenue (this is done by replacing gross revenue in these equations with net revenue). This may be somewhat unrealistic in the case of agricul- ture, although variable costs are relatively minor in this case, representing only 9% of the value of agricultural output (Ministers du Plan, 1988). This assumption is more realistic for commerce, a sector in which intermediate expenses are quite important. The third issue is how to deal with imbalances between net income and total expenditure at the household level. Although income and expenditure are highly correlated, there are important differences due to saving and dissaving, transfers, and measurement error. Perhaps the most conservative approach is to assume that-a given change in net income results in a change in expenditure of the same proportion. Under these assumptions, the short-run effect of prices on income is simulated using the proportion of net income for each household obtained from each type of activity. This information is available from the ENBC data. Urban income was classified into 15 categories, while rural income was divided into 24 groups. 4.4.2 Su r o s of a riculture Simulating the long-run effect of prices on income requires data on the supply response, particularly for agricultural commodities. The ENBC data set is not appropriate for estimating agricultural-supply elasticities because land, labor, and input use are not available at the level of individual crops. In this study, we make use of agricultural price supply elastici- ties estimated for Rwanda by Ansoanuur (1991). The estimates are based on time-series data covering the period 1971-1989. Production data were assembled from the Ministry of Agriculture and the export marketing boards, while price information was obtained from Ministry of Planning sources. The double-log functional form was used in most cases, although the semi-log form was adopted in a few cases where it yielded a closer fit. 93 The dependent variable was the volume of production in most cases, although the number of trees was used in the coffee equation. The independent variables (expressed in log form) included the price of the commodity, the legal minimum wage deflated by the consumer price index, the real price of hoes, and the level of rainfall. In the case of coffee and tea, three years of lagged prices were added to reflect the lag between new planting and new production. The price of other crops was also added in the case of a few pairs of close substitutes (white potatoes and pyrethrum, bananas and coffee, and beans and sorghum). There are a number of limitations of this approach to modeling the household as produCer: l) labor-leisure decisions are not explicitly modeled, 2) estimates are based on single-equation regressions using only a few prices, and 3) few of the estimated elasticities are signifie cantly different from zero, perhaps reflecting the low quality of the original data. On the other hand, the supply elasticities are well within the range of those estimated for the same crops in other less developed countries (see Askari and Cummings, 1976). Furthermore, the direct price effect on income, which is estimated more accurately, is likely to be more important than the output effect. 4.5 Price changes associated with devaluation The next phase involves adopting some set of price changes associated with devaluation. This information is combined with the model of household behavior described in sections 4.3 and 4.4 to simulate the impact on household welfare and nutritional intake, as described in section 4.6. Both historical and hypothetical prices are used, each with their own advantages and limitations. Each is discussed in turn. 94 4.5.1 Historicai ppice data The historical prices are based on monthly data collected by the Ministry of Planning in the capital city of Kigali during the year before and the six months after the October 1990 devaluation. This data source has the obvious advantage of simulating the actual price trends in the country. There are, however, several drawbacks to using these data. The most important complication is that an unsuccessful military invasion of the country took place in October 1990, making it difficult to isolate the effect of each event on prices. The invasion has resulted in significant security measures within the country and strained relations with neighboring countries, particularly Uganda and Burundi. The security measures have affected prices in various ways, particularly by impeding the internal flow of people and goods with checkpoints. The strained relations with Uganda have restricted trade between the two countries, as well as international trade which normally flows through Uganda to and from the coast. A second problem is that only five months of post-devaluation price data from Kigali are available. A longer time series and a sample of rural prices would be desirable. To the extent that the proportional change in prices varied across the country, this simulation may be biased. 4.5.2 Hypothetical prices The alternative approach is to adopt hypothetical prices according to a priori knowledge of the impact of devaluation and the nature of different goods and services in Rwanda. The literature on devaluation, reviewed in Chapter 3, focuses on the distinction between tradeable and non-tradeable goods. The rural component of the Rwandan household budget survey contains codes for 405 goods and services, while the urban component has codes for 825 goods and services. Each product was classified as tradeable or non-tradeable based on a judgement as to 95 whether the price of the product is determined by international markets or by domestic demand and supply. Although the judgement is somewhat arbitrary, in most cases the appropriate choice was obvious. Most of the staple food crops were considered non-tradeable because their low value/bulk ratio prevents any significant amount of international trade in these commodities. Export crops such as coffee, tea, and pyrethrum are obviously tradeable, as are imported foods such as rice, wheat flour, vegetable oil, and most processed items. Beans represent perhaps an intermediate case. 'First, imports represent around half of all marketed volume but only 15% of domestic consumption. Second, beans are imported informally so that the price is partly a function of the parallel exchange rate. In this study, it is assumed that the price increase for beans is one quarter that of pure tradeables (see Appendix A). All services were considered to be non-tradeable, while most manufactured goods were considered tradeable. Although a number of manufactured goods are produced in Rwanda, as described in Chapter 2, many of them compete directly or indirectly with imported products. Since the demand analysis is done at a much more aggregated level, with only 17 to 20 food categories and nine non-food groups, it was necessary to aggregate the tradeable-nontradeable information to this level. The price change for a given category is set equal to the weighted average of the assumed price change of tradeables and non- tradeables, with the weights equal to the tradeable and non-tradeable components of the category. The relationship between nominal devaluation and the relative Enrica of tradeables and non-tradeables is studied by Edwards (1989). UB:ing pooled time-series data for 12 less developed countries and a fixed-effect model, he estimates coefficients between 0.49 and 0.68, meaning that "with all other things as given, a nominal devaluation has been transferred in a less than one-to-one real devaluation in the first 96 year" (p. 141). Using a different specification and 29 devaluation episodes, he obtains an estimate of 0.60 for the year after devaluation (p. 268). In this study, we will adopt the latter figure. Thus, the November 1991 increase of 67% in the Rwandan exchange rate (expressed in francs per US dollar) would result in a 40% increase in the relative price of tradables within a year of devaluation. Although this study focuses on the effect of price changes associated with devaluation, the same methods could be used to simulate the effect of other hypothetical price changes. For example, changes in the administratively-set rates for water and electricity or variations in the price of individual food commodities could be modeled. Of course, the price changes would have to be at the level of aggregation of the budget categories used in the demand model. 4.6 ct of c han 3 At this point, we have described the methods for estimating a model of consumer demand, an approach for incorporating the effect of prices on income, and the use of both historical and hypothetical prices. In this section, we describe the methods for measuring the welfare impact and the nutritional impact of price changes on house- .holds. 4.6.1 Efifecp of pgice cganges on demand Because the functional form being used in this study does not have the property of exact aggregation, we cannot simulate the change in demand using a single demand equation of a representative household. Instead, the demand must be calculated for each household and then summed. For household h and good i, the quantity consumed can be written as follows: 97 X x q,”- = arm-(J .91.. z.) —” (4-45) P F51 where q“, - quantity of good i consumed by household h wufi-)- demand function describing budget share ' for good i and household h xh - total expenditure for household h P a Stone's price index to deflate expenditure ph s gxl vector of prices for household h zh a 3x1 vector of household characteristics for household h put a price of good i for household h The quantities can then be summed over households for.each good to obtain the aggregate quantities. .Prices affect demand in three ways: 1) directly through the price vector, ph, 2) indirectly through the price index, P, and 3) indirectly through total expenditure, xh, since income is a function of the prices of output. These three types of influence represent the substitution effect, the income effect, and the profit effect, respectively. 4.6.2 ct r ce c n es on utr tion The impact of price and income changes on nutritional intake is calculated by combining simulated changes in food consumption with the nutritional coefficients for each category of food. This can be expressed as follows: 9 _ ACb = 2 c, AgM (4-45) 1-1 where Dch = change in caloric or protein intake for household h c1 a coefficient relating the caloric or protein content per unit of good i dqm a change in consumption of good i by household h The precision of this method is related to the degree of disaggregation of the food categories. In this study, we use 17 food categories in the rural areas and 21 in the urban areas. Although the degree of disaggre- 98 gation is quite high for a demand analysis, it does contain some heterogeneous categories such as ”other meats" and "prepared meals.” A more finely disaggregated analysis of the Rwandan ENBC food consumption data was carried out using 180 food categories (see Mini- sters du Plan, 1988). Although the demand analysis cannot be carried out at this level of disaggregation, we can use these results to obtain average nutritional coefficients for the broader categories. Thus, the nutritional coefficient for "other meat" is based on a quantity-weighted average of 20 types of meat other than beef. Once again, the nutritional impact is calculated for each house- hold, based on the diet of that household, the sources of income, and the estimated food demand elasticities for that household. This allows us to make full use of the diversity of household behavior as reflected in the survey sample. 4.6.3 e o ‘ e cha es on ouseho d we fare In section 3.4, a number of approaches to measuring welfare impact were compared. In this study, we make use of seven measures: consumer surplus, three approximations of compensating variation, and three approximations of equivalent variations. They are summarized in Table 4-3. The first-order approximation of compensating variation (CV1) is the simplest and most commonly used welfare measure. It is the only measure which does not require any knowledge of the shape of the demand curve, relying entirely on the price and quantity data at the original position before the price change. The first-order approximation of the equivalent variation (EVI) is similar, but it uses the "after” quantity rather than the ”before" quantity. The expressions for CV1 and EV1 are given in equations 3-43. Graphically, these measures may be considered "rectangular” approximations of EV and CV, as shown in Figure 3-2. Consumer surplus (CS) is approximated as a trapezoid, that is, as a Second-order approximation of the "true” consumer surplus. Although 99 Table 4-3: Selected welfare measures IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-II Symbol Measure Approximation method CV1 .Compensating variation First-order approximation CV2 Compensating variation Second-order approximation cvi Compensating variation Vartia method (n iterations) CS Consumer surplus Second-order approximation Eva Equivalent variation Vartia method (n iterations) EV; Equivalent variation ‘ Second-order approximation EV1 Equivalent variation Firstforder approximation this measure is not well-defined for multiple price and income changes, as discussed in the previous chapter, it is calculated in this study as a basis of comparison with the willingness-to-pay measures. Equation 3- 34 is used to calculated consumer surplus. The two second-order approximations (EV: and CV2) are calculated using the Hicks method which involves a Taylor-series expansion of the expenditure function. The expressions for these two welfare measures are given in equations 3-44 and 3-45. Graphically, these may be thought of as "trapezoidal" approximations of CV and EV, as illustrated in Figure 3-3. The Vartia approximation of compensating variation (CVh) and equivalent variation (svn) involve an interactive procedure, as de- scribed in section 3.4.4, so it cannot be expressed as an equation. In this study, twenty iterations are used to calculate this welfare measure, although some experimentation is done with 50 iterations. Each of these measures includes a term for the change in net income (or profit) due to changes in output prices. This term (Ax) can be calculated using short-term producer surplus or long-term producer surplus, given in equations 3-31 and 3-32 respectively. Because of 100 uncertainty regarding the supply elasticities, most of the results are calculated using the short-term producer surplus which assumes no supply response. However, sensitivity analysis is used to explore the impact of incorporating supply response in the model. Consumer surplus and the two 'willingess-to—pay” measures are expressed in monetary terms, yet clearly the utility derived from one Rwandan franc is not the same across households. No attempt is made to measure or assume a relationship between the marginal utility of money and household income. Nonetheless, in order to incorporate, at least in a rough way, the idea that the marginal utility of money declines with income, the results are presented as a percentage of household expendi- ture. For example, substituting equation 3-31 into 3-45, we can write CV1 as a proportion of expenditure as follows: CV1.” 531 N 4%1 x ‘4‘?! X; 7A?! .1 x (4-47) N Ap " Ap 3 2:131 1 ‘ zz'GI——i .1 pl .1 pi where f0, is the base-period share of net income from good i and wb1.is the base-period share of total expenditure allocated to good i1. This is the measure used by Sahn and Sarris (1991). As they note, this measure overestimates the welfare loss of consumer price increases and underestimates the welfare gain from output price increases because it does not incorporate household response to price changes. Expressing the welfare impact as a percentage of household expenditure allows for an intuitively simply interpretation of the results. EV/x is the percentage change in real income equivalent to the price changes being simulated. Similarly, CV/x is the percentage of 1. Strictly speaking, this interpretation requires the assumption that expenditure is equal to net income. 101 real income which would be necessary to compensate the household for the price changes. Each of these welfare measures is calculated for each household in the sample, based on the sources of net income, the structure of consumption, and the demographic composition of the individual house- holds. Only then are the welfare measures averaged over different groups of households defined by region, occupation, or income. In this way, the full diversity of households in the sample is exploited. CHAPTER 5 HOUSEHOLD BUDGET PATTERNS IN RWANDA In this chapter, the basic results of the National Household Budget and Consumption Survey (ENBC) are presented to provide context for the discussion in the chapters to follow. Section 5.1 reviews the characteristics of Rwandan households. In section 5.2, the composition of household income is described. Section 5.3 analyzes the level of total expenditure which is used as an indicator of household welfare and the composition of expenditure across different types of households. Finally, section 5.4 provides additional analysis of the agricultural economy of Rwanda. 5.1 wa d 0 1d This sections presents a brief overview of the basic demographic characteristics of Rwandan households. For the purposes of the ENBC, the household is defined as a group of people, generally related, that live and eat together. Under this definition, semi-permanent "guests" and domestic employees are included in the household, but family members who live elsewhere are not. . . The average household in Rwanda has 4.9 people, including 2.7 adults and 2.3 children, as shown in Table 5-1. The heads of household average somewhat less than 48 years of age, and about one fifth of the heads of household are female. These national averages are determined primarily by the rural sector, which accounts for about 95% of the total. It is useful to compare urban and rural households. Urban households tend to be younger than rural households, as shown in Table 5-1. Less than a tenth of the urban heads of household are over 60 years of age, whereas almost a quarter of the rural heads of household are. As a consequence, urban households are more likely to be 102 103 in the child-bearing years: 57% of the heads of household in the cities are 40 years or less in age, while only 36% of the rural heads are in this age group. Table 5-1: Characteristics of rural and urban households Rural Urban Total Avg age of head of household 48.2 40.4 47.8 Pct of households by age 30 or under 16.8 % 29.3 % 17.4 % 31-40 years 19.3 % 27.3 % 19.7 % 41-50 years 22.1 % 22.4 % 22.1 % 51-60 years “ 17.3 % 12.1 % 17.2 % Over 60 years 24.5 % 9.0 % 23.7 % Total . 100.0 % 100.0 % 100.0 % Average size of household 4.9 -5.6 4.9 Number of adults 2.7 2.4 2.7 Number of children 2.3 3.2 2.3 Pct households by size 1-3 people 26.2 % 28.2 % 26.3 % 4 people 13.8 % 18.4 % 14.0 % 5 people 12.5 % 15.3 % 12.6 % 6 people 10.6 % 15.0 % 10.8 % 7 or more people 36.9 % 23.1 % 36.2 % Total 100.0 % 100.0 % 100.0 % Pct of households with female head of household 20.6 % 16.6 % 20.4 % Source: Rwandan ENBC. Urban households are also larger than rural households, on average. As shown in Table 5-1, this difference is due to the larger number of children in urban households. One explanation for this pattern is that a higher proportion of urban households are in child- bearing years, as discussed above. Another factor is that children and adolescents from rural households often migrate to the city, staying with relatives while attending school or looking for work. Urban households are somewhat less likely to be female-headed. In both urban and rural areas, female heads of household are, on average, older and have smaller households than their male counterparts. 104 About 38% of urban female head are 40 years or under in age, and just 12% of rural female heads are in this age group. This may reflect the importance of widows among the female-headed households, particularly in the rural sector. 5.2 Compggitiop of household income 5.2.1 Qgiinition of net igcome For the purposes of this study, net income is the value of production minus the value of business expenses. Production includes agricultural home production, cash sales of goods and services, goods and services "sold" through barter, and goods and services offered as transfers. The sale or transfer of household assets is excluded intentionally, while the value of non-agricultural home production is excluded for lack of data. Business expenses include the value of labor, raw materials, inputs, and land rental, whether purchased in cash or through barter. In the case of merchants, it also includes the goods purchased for resale. The purchase of vehicles, land, or commercial property is excluded from business expensesl. Net income is less suitable than total expenditure as an indicator of household welfare for three reasons. First, welfare is a function of material well-being (among other factors) and is thus more directly measured by expenditure than income. _Second, net income is calculated as the difference between two estimated values (gross income and business expenses), so it is less accurately measured than expenditure. Third, households probably "smooth" expenditure relative to income by means of saving and dissaving. Seasonal smoothing implies that annual expenditure is more accurately measured than annual income, while year- 1. These transactions would properly be included in a capital account category. However, because infrequent transactions are not well measured in this type of survey, no analysis of capital accounts was attempted. 105 to-year smoothing implies that expenditure is an estimate of "permanent income" as perceived by the household. Given the fact that net income is less appropriate for measuring household welfare, household welfare and distributional issues will be discussed in the context of household expenditure in section 5.3. This section concentrates on the sources of income for Rwandan households. 5.2.2 r io ncom om d’f e e t ct'v t‘es The agricultural sector, which includes both crop and animal production, is the most important source of net income in Rwanda. It represents 55% of the net income of Rwandan households, according to the ENBC data presented in Table 5-2. Of course, most of this production is in the rural areas, where agriculture represents 62% of net income, but agriculture exists on a small scale in the cities as well. The importance of agriculture would be even greater under a broader definition. In Table 5-2, beer income is calculated by implicitly including the value of the raw materials (bananas and sorghum),when they are grown by the same household that brews the beer. Reclassifying this banana and sorghum production as agriculture would raise the share of agriculture to approximately 74% of rural net income (Ministry of Planning, 1988: Annex D). Manufacturing and services includes the output of selfeemployed non-agricultural producers and service providers such as beer brewers, tailors, wood- and metal-workers, masons, mechanics, bar and restaurant owners, and truck drivers. The importance of this sector does not vary much between the rural and urban areas (24% and 30%, respectively), but these figures mask important differences in composition. In the countryside, beer brewing is the dominant activity within this sector. Banana beer alone accounts for over 60% of the value of rural manufacturing and services. In the cities, by contrast, beer brewing is a minor activity compared to construction, repair work, transportation, 106 Table 5-2: Sources of net income for rural and urban households — Source of income Rural Urban Total TOTAL 100.0 % 100.0 % 100 % Agricultural production 62.1 % 5.3 % 55.1 Manufacturing and services 23.7 % 30.4 % 24.5 Beer brewing 17.5 % 2.3 % 15.6 Other 6.2 % 28.0 % 8.9 Commerce 5.4 % 20.4 % 7.3 Wage employment 8.7 % 44.0 % 13.1 Agricultural wages 4.0 % 0.7 % 3.6 Public sector _ 2.9 % 19.2 % 4.9 Other 1.8 % 24.0 % 4.6 Source: Rwandan ENBC. — food preparation, and wood working. This pattern of locational specialization in manufacturing can be attributed, in part, to the geographic distribution of demand. As a result of higher urban income and the consequent larger shares allocated to non-food items, real non-food expenditure per household in the urban areas is 6.2 times higher than in the rural areas. According to the ENBC data, urban households represent just 5% of the population, but account for over a quarter of the non-food demand. Another factor in the geographic distribution of manufacturing is that banana beer brewing is a weight-reducing process. _On average, three kilograms of bananas are needed for one kilogram of banana beer. Thus, transportation costs are reduced by brewing the beer on the farm where the bananas are grown. Indeed, over 90% of the bananas used in rural beer production are grown by the brewer household. By contrast, sorghum beer brewing is a weight-adding activity, with less than 100 grams of sorghum being needed for one kilogram of sorghum beer. This helps explain why only half of the sorghum used in rural sorghum beer production is grown by the brewer household. It also explains the fact that rural brewing activity is dominated by banana 107 beer, while urban beer production is primarily in the form of sorghum beer (Ministry of Planning, 1988: Annex D). Commerce refers to the purchase and resale of goods with little or no physical transformation of the product. This category includes the entrepreneurial income of all types of traders, from large-scale diversified importer-wholesalers to small-scale retailers without employees. As presented in Table 5-2, commerce is almost four times as important as a source of household income in the urban sector as in the rural sector. This is not surprising given the fact that much of rural production is not marketed. The level of commercial income as a proportion of the value of cash expenditures is similar in rural and urban sectors (15% and 21% respectively). Wage income is defined as income earned on a per-hour or per- month basis. Table 5-2 demonstrates that this is an important source of income in the urban areas, representing 44% of the total. Somewhat more than half of urban wage income is earned through non-agricultural private sector employment, while public sector employment accounts for almost all the remainder. By contrast, wage income is much less important in the rural areas, contributing less than 9% of the total. Almost half of this take the form of agricultural wage labor. 5.2.3 zgopoptiop of households by primapy occupation .Another way to evaluate the importance of different sources of income is to look at the distribution of households according to the primary source of income, defined as that which contributes over 50% of household net income. Table 5-3 indicates that almost three- quarters of all Rwandan households derive most of their income from farming. In absolute terms, by this definition, there are approximately 800,000 farm households in Rwandal. About 10% of Rwandan households are self-employed in manufacturing and services, while the remaining 16% 1. To fully appreciate the farming intensity in Rwanda, it is worth noting that by a similar definition there are approximately 600,000 farm households in the United States (Tweeten, 1989). 108 of the households are more or less equally divided among commerce, wage employment, and ”diverse” (i.e. households for which no single source of income accounts for over half the total). Overall, about 88% of Rwandan households obtain at least half of their net income from self- employment. Table 5-3: Distribution of households by primary occupation Principal occupation Rural Urban Total TOTAL ' . ' 100.0 % 100.0 % 100.0 % Agriculture 76.9 % 14.0 % 73.7 % Manufacturing and services 8.7 % 28.6 % 9.7 % Commerce 3.7 % 11.5 % 4.1 % Wage employment 4.4 % 35.3 % 5.9 % Diverse 6.3 % 10.5 % 6.5 % Source: Rwandan ENBC. In the rural sector, 77% of the households depend primarily on agriculture to earn their living. Furthermore, the prOportion would be even higher if the banana and sorghum production of brewers were counted as agriculture. Nonetheless, it is important to note that even in this semifisubsistence low-income rural economy, almost one quarter of the households derive most of their income from non-agricultural activities. In the cities, wage employment is the most common primary occupation, but only 35% of the households fall into this category. This statistic highlights the danger of using wage rates as an indicator of well-being in Rwanda, even among the urban population. Furthermore, as discussed below, households whose primary source of income is wage income tend to have higher-than-average incomes. Over half (54%) of the urban households derive most of their income from self-employment in agriculture, manufacturing and services, and commerce. For the 109 remaining 10% of the households, no one activity accounts for over half of net income. 5.2.4 ort' f households 'nvolved in d erent activities Having reviewed the distribution of households according to the primary source of income, it is useful to consider supplemental sources of income. Table 5-4 shows the proportion of households obtaining any income from each source. The ENBC data indicate that all the rural households and three-quarters of the urban households have some agricultural production. The latter figure may seem high, but it should be recalled that households with a garden, fruit trees, or a plot outside the city are included. Virtually all rural households and about half the urban household brew banana or sorghum beer, whether or not it is marketed. Although wage employment is a secondary source of income for most rural households, about 44% of them obtain some income from agricultural wage labor. Table 5-4: Proportion of households earning any income from each source — Source of income Rural Urban Total Agricultural production 100.0 %' 75.5 % 98.7 % Manufacturing and services 97.7 % 83.2 % 97.0 % Beer brewing 96.5 % 49.3 % 94.1 % Other . 42.3 % 70.4 % 43.7 % Commerce 27.3 % 51.0 % 28.5 % Wage employment 52.1 % 67.3 % 52.9 % Agricultural wages 44.1 % 13.3 % 42.5 % Public sector 5.0 % 24.6 % 6.0 % Other 14.9 % 48.2 % 16.6 % Source: Rwandan ENBC. An index of the diversity of income sources is the sum of the ‘— percentsges of households obtaining income from each source. If the list of sources is exclusive and exhaustive, this sum represents the average number of sources of income per household. Dividing the sources 110 into five categories (agriculture, brewing, other manufacturing and services, commerce, and wage employment), the sum is over 300% in both urban and rural sectors. This means that Rwandan households, on average, obtain income from slightly more than three of these five income sources. 5.3 Compggitiog gf household eipendipuge 5.3.1 Definition of expgnditupg For the present purposes, total expenditure is defined as the sum of cash consumption expenditures and the imputed value of agricultural home production, gifts received in kind, and goods received in barter transactions. Cash consumption expenditures includes current consumption expenditures (e.g. food) and expenditure on durables (e.g. household effects), but excludes purchases of vehicles, land, and buildings. It also excludes goods purchased to be used as gifts for other households to avoid double countingl. Non-agricultural home production was not recorded in the ENBC, although estimates derived from the Household Asset questionnaire indicate that this is negligible, even in the rural areas. The collection of firewood, on the other hand, may be a significant type of non-agricultural home production (see Ministers du Plan, 1988). Household expenditures need to be adjusted for household size and composition in order to more accurately reflect the average standard of living in the household. For the present purposes, we use both expenditure per capita and expenditure per adult equivalent (ae), where the latter is defined on the basis of caloric requirementsz. The 1. In the rural areas, ”product use" codes allowed the exclusion of goods purchased to be used as gifts. In the urban areas, the value of gifts given was subtracted from consumption expenditures for the appropriate budget category. 2. 'Each member of the household is assigned a value, based on age and gender, to reflect his or her caloric requirements as a fraction of those of an adult male. For example, a five-year-old girl 111 estimation of adult-equivalence scales based on the budget data is a more theoretically justifiable approach, but there is little agreement on the correct method (see Deaton and Case, 1988). And finally, nominal figures need to be adjusted for the price level in each region. Price indices were calculated based on the prices recorded in the ENBC of 32 products, representing about 70% of the value of household expenditures nation-wide. A price index was calculated for each of the five geographic zones in the rural areas and each of the four urban centers. Kigali is used as the base region. 5.3.2 vera e end e d st b The average level of expenditure in Rwanda according to the ENBC is 13,422 Rwandan francs (FRw) per person per year at current prices (1983 for rural expenditure and 1985 for urban) or 18,670 FRw per capita at Kigali prices of 1985. Given the 1985 official exchange rate of 100 Frw per U.S. dollar, nominal expenditure is equivalent to $ 134 per capita. The World Bank estimate of 1982 per capita gross national product is $ 260 (World Bank, 1984). The difference is partly due to the fact that gross national product includes several categories excluded from this estimate, such as savings and government expenditure. One study compared over a dozen household budget surveys and found that survey estimates of income (or expenditure) were almost always lower that those of national accounts (Brown et a1., 1978). As shown in Table 5-5, the level of real expenditure per capita is about 2.4 times higher in the urban areas than in the rural areas. When household size is measured using adult equivalents, the ratio is almost the same. The urban/rural ratio of real expenditure per capita (2.4) is considerably lower than that of nominal expenditure per household (almost 4.0) for two reasons. First, the average household size in the cities (5.6 persons) is greater than that in the country (4.9). Second, is given a value of 0.76 since her caloric needs are roughly three quarters those of an adult male (see Appendix A for the equivalence scale). 112 prices are about 50% higher in the urban areas, particularly those of domestically produced food. These results highlight the importance of adjusting for prices and household size when comparing urban and rural expenditure. Table 5-5: Mean level of expenditure in rural and urban areas — Urban/ Rural Urban rural National average average ratio average Nominal expenditure FRw/household/year 54,360 214,807 3.95 62,543 FRw/person/year 11,763 44,302 3.77 13,422 FRw/ae/year 13,095 49,026 3.74 14,934 Real expenditure FRw/household/year 80,245 210,706 2.63 86,923 FRw/person/year 17,396 42,285 2.43 18,670 FRw/ae/year 19,352 46,846 2.42 20,759 Note: ”as" refers to adult-equivalent, where the number of adult equivalents in the household reflects the caloric requirements of the household, based on the age and sex of its members Source: Rwandan ENBC. A brief examination of the distribution of expenditure among households demonstrates that the gap between the urban and rural averages is not just the result of a few high-income households in the urban areas. Table 5-6 shows, for example, that scarcely one quarter of the rural households reach the level of 20,000 FRw/person/year, whereas almost three quarters of the urban households exceed this level. Another illustration of the generally higher incomes in the cities is that 73% of the urban households have per capita expenditure levels above that of the national median (18,250 FRw/person/year). According to various measures of concentration, expenditure is more concentrated in the urban areas than in the rural areas. For example, the poorest 20% of the rural households account for 14% of 113 Table 5-6: Cumulative distribution of households by expenditure level Real expenditure Rural Urban National (FRw/person/year) 5,000 - 9,999 13.9 % 4.6 % 13.4 % 10,000 - 14,999 51.7 % 12.9 % 49.9 % 15,000 - 19,999 72.4 % 26.3 % 70.0 % 20,000 - 24,999 82.9 % 39.4 % 81.9 % 25,000 - 29,999 90.0 % 49.0 % 87.9 % 30,000 - 34,999 95.2 % 56.0 % 93.2 % 35,000 - 39,999 97.9 % 63.3 % 96.1 % 40,000 and above 100.0 % 100.0 % 100.0 % Source: Rwandan ENBC. — total expenditures in the rural areas, whereas the poorest 20% of the urban households represent just 7% of the urban total. Similarly, the Gini coefficient for the rural areas is 0.27, while the urban coefficient is 0.42. Because the overwhelming majority (roughly 95%) of the Rwandan population is rural, the distribution of expenditure is largely determined by the rural patterns. Thus, the poorest 20% of the households in Rwanda, according to the ENBC, represent 13% of total household expenditures and the Gini coefficient is 0.29. This indicates that Rwanda has one of the least concentrated expenditure distributions ‘in the world, albeit at one of the lowest levels of average expenditure (income) in the world. 5.3.3 Expenditure for different typgg of households The level of per capita expenditure varies as a function of a number of household characteristics, most importantly occupation, size of household, and sex of head of household. The households in the ENBC were divided into different five occupations depending on the most important source of net income: agriculture, manufacturing and services, cOmmerce, wage employment, and ”diverse” (the last category was for INDuseholds for which no one source represented at least 50% of the tOtal) . 114 In both urban and rural areas, the wage earners have the highest incomes and expenditures, as shown in Table 5-7. Although there are some day laborers and other low-income wage earners, most of the wage earners are teachers, civil servants, and other relatively well-paid occupations. Artisans and merchants tend to have expenditure levels close to the average of their regions. Although merchants are perceived in Rwanda as wealthy, the ENBC results imply that there are a large number of small-scale (lower—income) merchants. Farmers and "diversified earners” have the lowest level of expenditure and income. Although these patterns hold in'both urban and rural areas, urban households have higher levels of expenditure within the same occupational category. The level of per capita expenditure is also correlated with the size of household, as shown in Table 5-7. In both urban and rural areas, larger households have lower average per capita expenditure. Deaton and Case (1988) note that this pattern exists in most household budget surveys and caution against interpretingthis~a7 a sign that household welfare falls with larger families-. First there may be I economies of scale in household size.(;Secon9,/larger households usually have a larger proportion of children, of’whom expenditure requirements are lower. This issue cannot be solved without more in-depth analysis, but it is worth noting that, if adulteequivalents are defined by caloric requirements, then expenditure per adult-equivalent also falls with larger households. Third, the sex of the head of household is a determinant of expenditure per capita. As shown in Table 5-7, male-headed households in the urban areas have per capita expenditure levels substantially higher than those of female-headed households. Part of this is due to the fact that female—headed households in the urban areas tend to be involved in less remunerative occupations, such as farming and small- scale commerce. This in turn could be the result of lower education and 115 Table 5-7: Real expenditure of different types of households Real expenditure (Frw/person/year) Rural Urban National average average average Principal occupation Agriculture 16,491 19,740 16,523 Manuf./services 20,583 46,208 24,443 Commerce 18,251 37,994 21,073 Wage employment 24,668 53,509 33,444 Diverse 18,517 28,691 19,363 Household size 1-3 members 21,742 56,356 23,393 4 members 17,250 46,820 18,399 5 members 16,193 38,375 17,133 6 members 14,930 36,912 15,737 Over 6 members 14,597 _ 33,465 ' 16,095 Sex of head of hh . Male 17,247 44,888 18,729 Female , 17,967 29,243 18,437 Overall mean 17,396 42,285 18,670 Note: Expenditure is evaluated at 1985 Kigali prices. Source: Rwandan ENBC. — literacy levels, limited access to credit, discrimination by employers, and/or social norms against participation in some occupations. Interestingly, there is no gap between the expenditure levels of male- and female-headed households in the rural areas. Perhaps this is because, although rural women probably face the same problems as urban women, education, credit, and discrimination are less constraining in farming, which is the predominant activity in the rural sectorl. 5.3.4 Composipion of expenditure Household expenditures in Rwanda are dominated by food, particularly tubers, plantains, and beans. Nationwide, over three m quarters of household expenditures (including the value of home .- "“‘“"‘""hfi~s~ . - 1. .mmr.ammo v p-“nnnmw‘i. ‘I'. It a J “L" ‘ 'M M term. mm-jn\g‘|_- 1. The use of purchased inputs, and hence the need for credit, is very limited in Rwanda. Expenditure on all agricultural inputs including labor is only 8% of the gross value of crop production. 116 production) are devoted to food products, as shown in Table 5-8. Tubers and bananas represent fully one quarter of expenditures, while legumes (primarily beans) account for almost one fifth. The next most important category is beverages, primarily traditional beers, which account for 15% of the value of expenditure. Animal products and grains, by contrast, are relatively minor items in the Rwandan budget, representing about 7% and 4% respectively. Only 22% of expenditure is allocated to non-food categories, the most important of which are housing (8%) and clothing (5%). Table 5-8: Composition of expenditure in rural and urban areas Expenditure category Rural Urban National Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 Food 80.7 54.2 77.4 Grains 3.4 5.0 3.6 . ers and plantains 27.2 12.6 25.4 egumes 21.3 6.9 19.5 Fruits and vegetables 1 3.4 3.1 3.3 Meat, eggs, and dairy 6.7 8.5 6.9 TKBeverages 15.9 11.2 15.4 Other 2.7 6.9 3.3 Non-food 19.3 45.9 22.6 Clothing 5.0 4.9 5.0 Housing 7.1 14.3 8.0 Household equipment 1.9 3.9 2.1 Energy and water 1.0 5.7 1.6 Health and hygiene 1.6 3.4 1.8 .Education 0.5 1.4 0.6 Transportation 1.1 7J8 1.9 Tobacco 0.6 1.1 0.7 Leisure and services 0.5 3.3 0.8 Source: Rwandan ENBC. Naturally, the composition of expenditure varies sharply between urban and rural areas. In the urban areas, barely one half (54%) of expenditures are allocated to food, whereas over four fifths (81%) of rural expenditures are on food. This difference is almost entirely due to the significantly larger shares of the rural budget allocated to 117 tubers, bananas, and legumes. These food categories account for 48% of the rural budget, but less than 20% of the urban budget. In contrast, the urban households allocate a larger share of their expenditures to housing, transportation, and energy and water than do rural households. In interpreting these figures, it is important to recall that real per capita expenditure is about 2.4 times greater among urban households than among rural households. Thus, even when the urban budget share is smaller than the rural share, the absolute level of expenditure on a given item is often higher in the urban areas. For example, the only category for which rural households spend more in absolute terms than urban households is legumes. 5.4 c e n u a sector 5.4.1 Lgng Given the overwhelming importance of agriculture in Rwanda and the high population density, access to arable land is obviously an important factor in the well-being of rural households. Data on the farm size is available for the rural sample of the ENBCI. These data indicate that the average farm size in the ENBC sample was 1.28 hectares. Almost 60% of the households in the sample had less than one hectare. Furthermore, the situation today is undoubtedly worse: in the decade.since these measurements were made, the population of Rwanda has probably grown by roughly 40%. The Gini coefficient of the distribution of land in the rural sector of Rwanda is 0.48.‘ This coefficient means that the degree of concentration of land ownership in Rwanda is somewhat above the African average, but far below that of most Latin American countries. In more 1. In 1982, the pilot survey of the Agricultural Census measured land area for 450 rural households. The following year, a subsample of 270 households was used for the rural portion of the ENBC. However, no land area information is available for four of the households in the rural ENBC sample. Thus, the farm size figures presented here are based on the remaining 266 rural households. 118 concrete terms, 52% of the farm land is farmed by one fifth of the rural households. Surprisingly, there no clear positive relationship between total farm size and household well-being, whether the latter is measured in caloric intake or expenditure per adult equivalent. Table 5-9 shows that the relationship is, if anything, curvilinear, with the smallest and largest farms being better off. Table 5-93‘ Rural expenditure and caloric intake by farm size — Real Caloric Parm size expenditure intake (hectares) (FRw/person/yr) (kcal/ae/day) Under 0.38 17,898 2,546 0.38 to 0.65 16,808 2,455 0.66 to 1.07 15,955 2,351 1.08 to 1.90 18,923 2,309 Over 1.90 17,832 2,573 Note: Farm size categories represent quintiles (each contains 20% of the rural households). Source: Rwandan ENBC/Rural sector. Three factors can be cited to explain this result. First, part of the Variability in farm size is due to life-cycle patterns. Average farm size increases and then decreases with the age of the head of household, tracking the growth and later decline of household size, as shown in Table 5-10. In other words, land ownership per capita is somewhat more equal than land ownership per household. The Gini coefficient for farm size per adult equivalent is 0.45, compared to 0.48 for total farm size. 119 Table 5-10: Life cycle patterns in farm size in the rural sector Age of head of Average Average size household size of of farm (years) household (hectares) Under 30 years 3.9 0.7 31-40 years 5.4 1.5 41-50 years 6.0 1.4 51-60 years 5.8 1.7 Over 60 years 3.7 1.1 Source: Rwandan ENBC/Rural sector. Second, the land is more intensively cultivated on small farms. Although net agricultural income1 per household rises with farm size, it does not increase proportionately. As shown in Table 5-11, the agricultural return per hectare is over six times as great on the smallest 20% of farms compared to the largest 20%. Much of the reason for this is related to soil fertility, which is probably inversely related to farm size. Average farm size is the greatest in the drier and less fertile eastern lowlands and the lowest in the fertile volcanic zones to the northwest. In addition, small farms tend to have more family labor per hectare of farmland (see Table 5-11). Thus, they are able to plant-more labor-intensive crops and use more labor-intensive techniques to increase return to the scarce factor, land. A third factor which reduces the importance of unequal land distribution is the fact that small farms rely more heavily on non- agricultural income. The last column in Table 5-11 indicates that the 1. Net agricultural income is the value of agricultural production (including home production) minus agricultural operating expenses, such as seed, hoes, chemicals, and hired labor. 120 Table 5-11: Factors which ameliorate the disparity in farm size — Avg size Persons Ag return Pct income Farm size household per per hect from non- (hectares) (persons) hectare (Frw/ha) ag source Under 0.38 3.6 17.5 104,731 35.5 t 0.38 to 0.65 4.6 9.6 56,631 19.6 t 0.66 to 1.07. 4.8 5.9 39,634 23.8 t 1.08 to 1.90 5.6 3.9 26,584 17.6 % Over 1.90 6.2 2.1 17,126 9.6 s Note: Farm size categories represent quintiles. Source: Rwandan ENBC/Rural sector. importance of income other than from agriculture and beer brewing1 increases from less than 10% among the largest 20% of farms to over 35% among the smallest 20\ of farms. It seems likely that farm size and non-agricultural income influence each other: small farmers are forced to supplement their income with non—farm activities and households with non-farm income are more likely to sell farm land they cannot adequately tend. Although total farm size is not related to household welfare, farm size per adult equivalent is positively related to welfare. As shown in the first pair of columns in Table 5-12, the mean expenditure level of the rural quintile under the least land pressure is 33% higher than that of the rural quintile under the greatest land pressure. Similarly, the mean caloric intake of the first group of households is 24% higher than that of the second. If we restrict our attention to rural households which obtain at least half of their net income from agriculture and beer brewing, then the relationship between farm size per adult equivalent and household welfare becomes stronger. This is particularly true if we use caloric 1. Since virtually all banana beer producers grow their own bananas, beer brewing is closely linked to banana production and thus to the availability of land. 121 Table 5-12: Rural expenditure and caloric intake by farm size Among rural households Among rural agricul- tural households Farm size Real Caloric Real Caloric per adult expenditure intake expenditure intake equivalent (FRw/person/ (kcal/ae/ (FRw/person (kcal/ae/ (hect/ae) year) day) /year) day) Under 0.10 15,725 2,230 14,538 2,151 0.11 to 0.18 16,089 2,352 15,568 2,319 0.19 to 0.27 17,209 2,594 17,025 2,596 0.28 to 0.47 18,194 2,389 17,173 2,398 Over 0.47 20,997 2,772 20,267 2,802 Note: Farm size categories represent quintiles. ”Agricultural” households are those that obtain at least 50% of net income from agriculture and beer brewing. Source: Rwandan ENBC/Rural sector. intake as the welfare indicator. One implication is that the situation of agricultural households under the greatest land pressure is especially acute, as shown in second pair of columns in Table 5-12. In summary, there is no relationship between total farm size and household welfare because 1) small farms households, 2) small farms have a higher and 3) small farms rely more on non-farm there is a positive relationship between and welfare, particularly for households agriculture for their income. 5.4.2 Purchased inputs Purchased inputs, services bought, either in cash or through barter, production (including livestock production). seeds, hoes, agricultural chemicals, 1. as defined here, agricultural labor, tend to be operated by small economic return per hectare, income. 0n the other hand, farm size per adult equivalent which rely primarily on refer to goods and for agricultural This category includes livestockl, Livestock were counted as a purchased input only when the household appeared to have a regular business of buying animals to fatten them for resale. 122 and rental of land. Although the vast majority of rural households (92%) purchase agricultural inputs, the value of these purchases is equivalent to only 9% of the value of agricultural production. This represents about USS 34 per household per year. Of the amount spent on purchased inputs, the largest share (40%) goes toward hired laborl. This is equivalent to about 17 days of hired labor per rural household per year. Since less than half the rural households (44%) hire labor, the average number of days of hired labor among those households is greater, about 39 days. Slightly less than half of rural households (46%) had members who worked as agricultural laborers for someone else. Livestock purchases are the second largest component, representing about 19% of the value of purchased inputs. The remaining 41% is split I more or less evenly among seeds and planting material, hoes and chemicals, and land rental. In spite of the land pressure in Rwanda, less than one quarter of the rural households purchase manure, fertilizer, or other chemicals. The average expenditure among users is roughly USS 6 per year. 5.4.3 Agricultural production and marketing As described in section 5.2, agriculture represents 62% of net income in the rural sector, and 77% of rural households earn over half their net income from crop and livestock production. Table 5-13 shows the percentage contribution of each commodity to the gross value of agricultural productionz. According to the ENBC data, the most important crops in terms of the value of production are bananas, beans, sweet potatoes, cassava, and white potatoes. It is interesting to note 1. This category also includes payment for specialist services such as veterinarians, but this component is negligible. 2. ‘It is "gross" in the sense that the cost of purchased inputs has not been subtracted. The contribution of each commodity to net income cannot be calculated because the ENBC data do not allow the input costs to be allocated among different crops. 123 that coffee, the predominant export commodity in Rwanda, is not among the top five crops. Table 5-13: Composition of agricultural production and sales — Pct of value Pct of value of of agricultural agricultural Commodity production sales Sorghum ‘ 4.4 6.5 Cassava 7.0 4.8 Sweet potatoes 12.7 3.8 White potatoes 6.2 . 7.9 Bananas ' 21.9 7.7 Beans 20.4 5.0 Fruits and vegetables 4.2 2.7 Coffee - y 4.3 21.7 Livestock ' 11.6 29.3 Other 7.3 10.6 TOTAL 100.0 100.0 Source: Rwandan ENBC/Rural sector. However, most of the agricultural output is retained on the farm for own-consumption. In value terms, more than three quarters (76%) of agricultural output is not marketed (the importance of home production is discussed further in section 5.5.1). The composition of agricultural sales is quite different, as shown in the second column in Table 5-13. Coffee and livestock alone account for one half of the value of agricultural sales by Rwandan households. Bananas, beans, and sweet potatoes, which represent 55% of the value of agricultural output, account for barely 16% of the cash revenue from agriculture. At the same time, it is worth pointing out that "food crops” as a whole contribute almost half of agricultural cash income, while "cash crops" barely account for one quarter. The proportion of the staple food production which is marketed varies considerably from one commodity to another, as shown in Table 5- 14. Less than 10% of the sweet potatoes, bananas, and beans produced in 124 Rwanda reach the market. The marketed shares of sorghum, cassava, white potatoes, and fruits and vegetables are greater but still less than one third of production. Table 5-14: Agricultural production and marketed share — Production Pct of output Commodity (kg/hh/yr) which is sold Sorghum 125.8 31.0 Cassava 306.3 20.5 Sweet potatoes 888.3 7.8 White potatoes 271.6 31.1 Bananas 1590.8 0.8 Beans 361.1 6.3 Fruits and vegetables 102.1 15.2 Coffee 16.8 100.0 Livestock 77.7 40.8 Source: Rwandan ENBC/Rural sector. Concerning sorghum and bananas, it should be noted that a portion of the "non-marketed" output is used by the same household to manufacture traditional beer, which may in turn be sold. Based on the volume of beer production, it appears that around 1,150 kilograms of bananas per household per year may be used directly in beer brewing by the producer. Roughly two thirds of the banana beer is marketed. Similarly, about 75 kilograms of sorghum per household per year are used to manufacture traditional beer by the grower. Slightly over half the sorghum beer production is sold. 5.5 Effect of prige changes on households In this section, we begin to examine the impact on households of the price changes associated with devaluation. Although a more rigorous model of household-level impact is developed in Chapter 7, the descriptive statistics presented in this section will facilitate the interpretation of the results of that chapter. 125 The effect on a given household of a price changes associated with devaluation can be crudely measured by considering the proportionate change in price, the composition of expenditure, and the sources of income. This type of analysis does not incorporate the effect of the adjustment of households as consumers and as producers, but it may serve as a first-round approximation. Thus, the absolute impact of a price increase of a given commodity would be the proportionate change in price times the difference between the value of production of that good and the value of consumption of the goodl. Of course, in subtracting the value of consumption (including home production) from the value of production (including home production), the result is the net cash sales of the good. The relative impact of the price increase can be approximated by the net cash sales as a proportion of total expenditure - (including home production). This discussion suggests that the effect of price changes associated with devaluation on a given household depends on 1) the level of participation in the market economy, 2) the net sales position of the household with respect to agricultural commodities, and 3) the tradeable component of cash expenditure and cash income. Each of these topics is explored in the following subsections. 5.5.1 a i ation 'n the market .The portion of total expenditure which is in the form of purchases (both cash and barter) clearly influences the vulnerability of the household to price changes. In other words, the larger the home produced component of expenditure (income), the more insulated the household is from fluctuations in pricesz. 1. This is the first-order estimate of compensating variation, i.e. the amount by which nominal income would have to be increased to restore the initial level of utility if (compensated) demand were completely inelastic (see equation 4-47). 2. The appropriate treatment for gifts and other transfers is not clear. In this section, we have included the value of transfers received with home production, since both are non-market acquisitions. 126 The first column of Table 5-15 indicates that, not surprisingly, home production represents a much larger share of rural food consumption than urban. Rural households produce over three quarters of their own food, as measured in terms of monetary value. The rate of food self- sufficiency in the urban sector is barely 20%, although this seems fairly high compared to the conventional view of urban life. Table 5-15: Importance of cash expenditure in rural and urban sectors — Home prod— .Food cons- Heme prod-' [Cash pur- uction as a umption as a. uction as a chases as a pct of food pct of total pct of total pct of total Sector' expenditure expenditure expenditure expenditure Rural 75.9 83.7 64.8 35.2 Urban 21.2 66.7 16.9 83.1 Rwanda 73.1 82.8 62.4 37.6 Source: Rwandan ENBC. The second column provides the mean share of total expenditure allocated to food consumption. The food share is, of course, higher in the rural areas, reflecting Engle's Law and the lower levels of expenditure in the countryside. _Food represents five sixths of the average rural budget, but only two thirds of the average urban budget. The product of these two ratios at the household level is the share of home-produced food in total expenditure, the average of which is presented in the third column of Table 5-15. Since data on non-food home production are not available from the survey data, this is our measure of the overall importance of home production. The portion of total expenditure in the form of cash purchases is thus one minus the home production share, as shown in the fourth column. Thus, purchases represent 35% of the expenditure of an average rural household and 83% of the expenditure of an average urban household. 127 The same information is disaggregated by expenditure quintile in Table 5-16. This table demonstrates that the role of home production in food consumption declines as income (expenditure per adult equivalent) rises. Similarly, the food share in the budget falls from 87% in the poorest fifth of households to 63% in the richest. These two factors together explain the sharp drop in the importance of home production from 62% of the budget in the first quintile to 19% in the fifth. Examined from another perspective, the importance of market purchases rises from somewhat more than one third to over four fifths of the total expenditure. Table 5-16: Importance of cash expenditure by expenditure quintile Home prod- Food cons- Home prod- Cash pur- Expendi- uction as a umption as a uction as a chases as a ture pct of food pct of total pct of total pct of total quintile expenditure expenditure expenditure expenditure lst 70.1 87.4 62.5 37.5 2nd 68.2 84.2 58.6 41.4 3rd 62.5 82.0 53.2 46.8 4th 55.8 80.0 46.8 53.2 5th 24.5 63.2 18.9 81.1 Rwanda 73.1 82.8 . 62.4 37.6 Source: Rwandan ENBC. The largest change in Table 5-16 occurs between the fourth and fifth quintiles. This raises the question as to whether the observed decline in the importance of home production is simply the result of urban households being clustered in the fifth quintile or whether this pattern exists separately in rural and urban sectors. In order to address this issue, Table 5-17 disaggregates the variables by rural quintile and urban quintile. 128 Table 5-17 reveals that the rate of food self-sufficiency does not vary appreciably across expenditure quintiles within the rural sector. In other words, relatively better off households in the rural sector are no more food self-sufficient than their poorer neighbors, nor do they depend any more on market purchases to obtain food. At the same time, the value of food consumption as a percentage of total expenditure does decrease as income rises, although the decline is fairly modest. The food share falls from 86% among the richest quintile to 80% in the poorest. Combining these two patterns, the share of home production in total expenditure declines gradually across expenditure quintiles. The importance of market purchases correspondingly rises from 32% among the poorest rural households to 38% among the richest. Table 5-17: Importance of cash expenditure by rural and urban expenditure quintiles _ Home prod- Food cons- Home prod- Cash pur- Expendi- uction as a umption as a uction as a chases as a ture pct of food pct of total pct of total pct of total quintile expenditure expenditure expenditure expenditure Rural sector lst 77.1 86.0 67.8 32.2 2nd 74.8 85.3 64.3 35.7 3rd 77.4 83.7 65.9 . 34.1 4th 75.1 - 83.1 63.5 36.5 5th 74.9 80.0 62.0 38.0 Urban sector lst 38.0 80.7 32.4 67.6 2nd 24.2 73.2 19.5 80.5 3rd 18.3 66.0 13.7 86.3 4th 14.3 59.3 11.5 88.5 5th 9.6 53.7 6.2 93.8 Source: Rwandan ENBC. — Turning our attention to the urban section, it is important to recall that the quintiles are defined relative to the income 129 distribution in each sector. For example, 60% of the urban households would qualify to be in the fifth rural quintile. Similarly, over half the rural households would be classified in the poorest urban quintile (see Table 5-6). According to Table 5-17, the patterns in the urban sector are much more marked than those in the rural sector. The importance of home production in food consumption drops sharply across expenditure quintiles, from 38% for the poorest fifth of urban households to under 10% for the richest. Likewise, food shares fall from almost 81% to 54%. As a result, the share of market purchases in total expenditure rises from two thirds among the poorest urban households to almost 94% among the richest. In summary, the importance of market purchases in total expenditure is positively related to the level of expenditure per adult equivalent. Furthermore, this pattern exists in both rural and urban areas. In the rural sector, the pattern is weak and is determined solely by the falling food share. In the cities, the pattern is strong and is determined by both a falling food share and falling food self- sufficiency as expenditure rises. As a result of these patterns, we can expect a given price change to have an effect on urban households at least twice as great as that on rural households. Furthermore, other things being equal, the impact will be fairly similar across rural households, but it will vary considerably among urban households. 5.5.2 Net position in agricultural commodities Even if two households have the same proportion of expenditure in the form of home production, the impact of a given price change will vary depending on the degree to which the hOuseholds are net sellers (or net buyers) of the good in question. Until recently, it was generally believed that rural households benefited from higher agricultural prices, with the possible exception of landless households that rely on wage-labor. However, recent research in Senegal (Goetz, 130 1990), Mali (Dione, 1989), and Rwanda (Loveridge, 1989) indicated that significant numbers of farmers are net buyers of staple crops (this research is summarized in Weber et al, 1988). This unexpected diversity in the rural sector indicates the need for more careful consideration of the net sales position of rural households. In particular, the welfare impact of various types of agricultural policy depends greatly on the distribution of households by their net sales position in different commodities. This applies to agricultural price policy, agricultural research priorities, and trade policy (including devaluation), among others. In the case of Rwanda, Loveridge (1989) found that 73% of Rwandan farmers were net buyers of beans and that 6% of the farmers accounted for over half of the net sales. Net buyers of beans depended more heavily on coffee and tea sales than net sellers. Furthermore, based on the imbalance between purchases and sales, he estimated that 15% of the national consumption of beans (and 60% of purchases) must have been imported. The survey data also indicated the existence of informal imports of sorghum. These conclusions were based on agricultural surveys of some 1000 farm households in 1985-86. Although the ENBC data set is older (1983) and based on a smaller sample (270 households) than that used by Loveridge, the breadth of the ENBC survey allows it to address some additional issues. In this section, we examine the net sales position for six principal crops, the degree of correlation in net position across crops, and the relationship between net sales and standard of living. Average net sales in the rural sector: Table 5-18 presents information on rural production, marketing, and consumption for seven crops, expressed in kilograms per rural household per year (kg/hh/yr). These results support the finding of Loveridge (1989) that rural purchases exceed sales for beans and sorghum. The ENBC figures imply that been imports represent 10% of rural consumption and 64% of 131 rural market purchases, estimates generally in line with those of Loveridge. In the case of sorghum, the calculation is complicated by the fact that a large portion of sorghum output is used in beer production, frequently by the same household. Based on ENBC estimates of traditional beer output and accepted transformation coefficients, self-supplied sorghum for beer brewing represents 75 kg/hh/yr on average (see Ministry of Planning, 1988, Appendix D). Taking this into account, apparent imports are 19% of rural usage (including that for beer brewing) and 43% of market purchases. Table 5-18: Rural production, marketing, and consumption of six crops _ Consumption of own Production production Sales Purchases Net sales Consumption Comodity (kg/hh/yr) (kg/hh/yr) (kg/hh/yr) (kg/hh/yr) (kg/hh/yr) (kg/hh/yr) Sorghum 121 8 38 67 -29 150 Maniac 298 236 62 30 32 266 Sweet pot. 854 790 64 48 16 838 White pot. 260 177 83 24 59 201 Banana 1691 520 115 77 38 1653 Beans 354 333 21 59 -38 392 Coffee 17 0 17 0 17 0 Note: Production is the sum of home production and sales. Consumption is the sum of home production and purchases. In the case of sorghum and banana, both production and consumption figures include the amounts used by the grower in the manufacture of traditional beer. This represents an estimated 1056 kg of bananas and 75 kg of sorghum per household per year. No allowance for self-stored seed is made in these calculations. Source: Rwandan ENBC/Rural sector. e In contrast, rural sales of the other staple food crops exceed rural purchases, according to the ENBC data. The surpluses (positive net sales) range from 16 to 59 kg/hh/year, depending on the crop. In order to assess the hypothesis that these surpluses are the volumes shipped to the urban areas of Rwanda, Table 5-19 presents the estimated rural surpluses (net sales) and urban market demand, both expressed in total tonnage. These figures are based on the extrapolation of ENBC figures to the national level. 132 Table 5-19: Rural net sales and urban demand Rural mkt Rural Urban mkt National demand surplus demand surplus as Commodity (1000 mt) (1000 mt) (1000 mt) % of cone. Sorghum 69.4 -30.1 8.5 -23 % Cassava 31.2 33.2 10.2 8 % Sweet potatoes 49.9 16.6 7.3 1 % White potatoes 24.8 61.2 37.2 10 % Bananas 80.0 39.4 11.8 2 % Beans 61.6 -39.4 9.6 -12 % Source: Rwandan ENBC. The national surplus (rural surplus minus urban market demand) is . under 10% of national consumption for manioc, sweet potatoes, and bananasl. This is probably within the margin of error for these estimates. In the case of white potatoes, the results may indicate exports to neighboring countries. This result confirms the conclusions of Ngirumwami (1989) who found frequent references to potato exports in interviews with Rwandan traders (see also Scott, 1988: 77). Table 5-19 also illustrates the fact that the bulk of the market demand for the basic staple crops is by rural households. It is often assumed that, because rural households rely on the market for only a small portion of their food consumption, agricultural sales must be destined for urban markets. For all the basic staples except white potatoes, rural market demand is three to eight times are great as urban demand. Thus, the principal agricultural marketing channels are rural- rural, with only relatively small volumes being siphoned off to meet urban demand. - 1. These calculations do not take into account agricultural sales by urban households. The value of urban agricultural sales indicates that the total volume for all crops is probably around six thousand metric tons. 133 White potatoes are the exception in that the cities account for 60% of the national market demand. This is related to the fact that white potatoes are a relatively expensive source of calories and are actually a ”luxury" good in the rural sector (see Tables 6-4 and 6-5). Qisppibutiog of householdg by net sales: Until now, the discussion has been confined to the net sales of different commodities for the "average" household. In this section, we explore the distribution of rural households according to their net sales position and examine the characteristics of net buyers and net sellers. Table 5-20 shows the percentage of rural households according to the type of participation in the markets for the six principal commodities. The proportion of rural households that participate in one way or another is around half for most commodities, but in the case of beans it is over 90%. The bean market is also unusual for the large percentage of rural households that are only purchasers (54%) and for the relatively small numbers of households that only sell (14%). Table 5-20: Distribution of households by market participation Percentage of households by market participation Buy and Neither buy Commodity Only buy Only sell ' sell nor sell Sorghum 32.7 23.7 5.8 37.8 Cassava 28.0 18.6 9.3 44.1 Sweet potatoes 26.8 22.2 2.6 48.4 White potatoes 32.2 11.9 2.1 53.9 Bananas 13.2 29.7 3.8 53.2 Beans 54.4 13.8 22.4 9.3 Only a small proportion of rural households both purchase and sell the same commodity: with the exception of beans, each commodity is both purchased and sold by less than 10% of rural households. This <=ontradicts the common belief that many farmers are forced to sell their <=xop at low harvest prices, only to buy some of it back at high prices 134 later in the season. Even in the case of beans, there is no evidence from the ENBC that households that buy and sell beans are poor households forced to make ”distress" salesl. More detailed information on net sales is provided in Figures 5-1 through 5-7 which show the cumulative percentage of rural households according to net sales of the six staple crops and coffee. Figure 5-1 provides the distribution for net sales of sorghum. Roughly half of the rural households are net buyers and one quarter are net sellers. The sharp "point" in the lower left portion of the graph indicates that net purchases are highly concentrated among a small number of households. This is due to the influence of relatively large-scale sorghum beer brewers who purchase their raw materials. The area above the curve and below the center line represents the total volume of net purchases, while the area under the curve and above the center line represents net sales. The fact that former exceeds the latter reflects the excess of purchases over sales in Rwanda, presumably made possible by informal sorghum imports. The distribution of households by net sales of cassava is quite different, as shown in Figure 5-2. About 30% of rural households are net buyers and 25% are net sellers, with close to half of the households having no net sales or net purchases. Purchases of cassava are less concentrated than those of sorghum, which is expected since most cassava purchases are for direct consumption. Sweet potatoes follow a similar pattern, as shown in Figure 5-3. One quarter of the rural households are net sellers, one quarter net buyers, and the remainder do not participate in the sweet potato market. Since virtually all rural households (94%) grow sweet potatoes, most of these non-participants grow sweet potatoes for their own consumption. 1. 'Bouseholds that both buy and sell beans in the rural sector tend to have average levels of expenditure and caloric intake and above-average levels of home production of beans. M eelee (WWW) (MI-ll“) I e e I hunk— I 0' mo. Figure 5-1: Distribution of households by net sales of sorghum 1.. 1.- .J 1.:J 1 a me- 0.0-1 0.4 - (men) 0.: _. let eelee (WWW) -0.I - .OA -. '°'. I I I I I I I I I hall‘ In. I 0' ml- Figure 5—2: Distribution of households by net sales of cassava According to Figure 5—4, white potatoes have a relatively even distribution of purchases among the 25% of rural households that buy them, but only 15% of rural households have net sales. Among the net sellers, a small proportion of households account for a large portion of the total volume. This concentration of production is due to the agro- m eelee (Wer) (MI-em) I o .I l “all..- I d ”I. Figure 5-3: Distribution of households by net sales of sweet potatoes , climatic requirements of potatoes which restrict them to fields above 1800 meters. In addition, there are a number of relatively large—scale commercial growers in the northwest (Scott, 1988: 61, 68). The overall rural surpluses in white potatoes is reflected in the greater area above the center line than below it. The distribution of rural households by net sales of bananas is shown in Figure 5-5. A relatively large portion of households (30%) have net sales. On the other hand, the net purchases of bananas are highly concentrated. As in the case of sorghum, this is the result of large-scale banana beer producers who need to purchase large quantities of raw materials. The net sales of beans are shown in Figure 5-6. There are several distinctive aspects of the pattern of net beans sales. First, the total volume of net purchases exceeds by a considerable margin the volume of net sales. As noted in the previous section, this appears to indicate informal imports of beans. Second, a large majority of rural households (70%) are net buyers of beans. Perhaps only one quarter of rural households have net sales. And third, unlike the other staple crops, MeeleetWWWJ (mm one um» I I l uni-else . e! her-duet. Figure 5-4: Distribution of households by net sales of white potatoes P u let eelee (WWW) (nausea) '3', I I I I I I I N 40 ” B-IIICIVI. I .9 ml- 81 5 Figure 5-5: Distribution of households by net sales of bananas beans are bOught and/or sold by almost all rural households. About 20% of all rural households have net purchases over 100 kg/yr, a quantity that represents roughly one quarter of the average household consumption. 138 am- mi -“1 ht eeIee (WWW) -mq F «no: I I I r I I I j 0 so 40 n_ O 1m “lens- I d var-l m0. Figure 5-6: Distribution of households by net sales of beans Finally, the distribution of rural households by the volume of coffee sales is presented in Figure 5-7. According to the ENBC data, about one third of the rural households sold coffee. Most coffee growers sell less than 100 kg/yr, but about five percent of rural households sell more than this amount. However, the ENBC may have underestimated coffee sales. The 1984 Agricultural Census, using a much larger sample, estimated that 44% of rural households were producing coffee. The Agricultural Census also estimated coffee production to be almost twice as high (32 compared to 17 kg/household/yr). These graphs have several implications for the impact of price changes on rural households. First, an increase in the price of beans will harm a large majority of rural households (70%), benefiting only one quarter of them. Second, changes in the price of the other staple crops (sorghum, cassava, sweet potatoes, white potatoes, and bananas) will generally benefit one quarter of the households, hurt another quarter, and not directly affect half of the rural households. Third, the impact (both positive and negative) will be relatively concentrated among a small number of households. This is particularly true in the 139 ht eelee (Whflw) l ”a n-I 40¢ ”a o I _ I T T fl f T I U 0 20 40 m ' n '100' Cami-elm I 0' mo. Figure 5-7: Distribution of households by coffee sales case of net sellers of white potatoes and the beer brewers who are net buyers of bananas and sorghum. Coprelation of pet sales across crops: The results in the previous section raise the question whether net buyers of one commodity tend to be net buyers of other commodities as well. One approach to answering this question is to consider the correlation of net sales, in volume terms, across commodities, shown in Table 5-21. In general, the correlation coefficients are fairly low: only three of the commodity pairs have net sales correlations greater than 0.15 in absolute value. The highest coefficient is that between net sales of beans and net sales of sorghum, although even this correlation is relatively weak (0.168). Another way to address this question is to consider the distribution of households according to their net sales of staple crops as a group. For this purpose, net sales of the six staple food crops, expressed in calories per adult equivalent (ae), have been summed for 140 Table 5-21: Correlation of net sales of different commodities — Sorghum Cassava Sw pot Wh pot Banana Beans Coffee Sorghum 1.000 Cassava .056 _1.000 Sw pot -.052 .044 1.000 Wh pot -.155 -.040 -.006 1.000 Banana .076 .135 -.164 .006 1.000 Beans .168 .133 .128 -.033 .147 1.000 Coffee .064 .125 -.003 -.089 -.008 .014 1.000 Source: Rwandan ENBC/Rural sector. — each householdl. Sorghum and banana purchases for beer brewing have been excluded in order to focus on food consumption. Figure 5-8 shows the cumulative distribution of households by the net sales (in kcal/ae/day) of the six staple food crops. Vbt eelee e! ecolee (Mel/eelw) (New 0 e 1 Gut-thee l of he‘s-reel- Figure 5-8: Distribution of households by net sales of six staple crops expressed in caloric terms This graph reveals that fully 45% of the rural households are net buyers of the six staple goods. However, many of the net buyers are 1. ' Net sales are expressed in calories to reflect more accurately the importance of each kilogram of the different crops and in per-adult-equivalent terms to adjust for household size. 141 purchasing relatively small amounts of these crops. Only about 5% of the rural households purchase more than 500 kcal/ae/day worth of the six staple crops. As a basis for comparison, the mean level of caloric intake in the rural sector is 2444 kcal/ae/day, according to the ENBC data. ghagaoteristics of net buvgpg: The distributional impact of a change in the price of an agricultural commodity obviously depends on the characteristics of net buyers and net sellers. It seems : plausible that net buyers could include poor households with g insufficient land to meet their own food needs and/or households with E relatively well-paying non-agricultural occupations. Table 5-22 5 provides some figures to help address these questions. a With respect to net sales of sorghum, it appears that households selling more than 100 kg/yr are relatively well-off. On the other hand, net buyers are better off in terms of expenditure and caloric intake than small-scale net sellers. This may be due to the influence of sorghum beer producers among the net buyersl. In the case of cassava and sweet potatoes, there is some evidence that the 15-20% of households with net purchases over 50 kg/yr have lower levels of food self-sufficiency, caloric intake, and expenditure. Net buyers of cassava tend to have smaller farms, but this is not the case for net buyers of sweet potatoes. However, it should be recalled that even among net buyers, home production is more important than purchases as a source of the commodity. White potatoes present a quite different pattern in which net buyers tend to be, if anything, better off than the 54% of rural household that neither buy nor sell potatoes. Large-scale net sellers (those with net sales of more than 100 kg/yr) have even higher levels of 1. The home production figures in this section of the table refer only to consumption of own production, excluding production retained for the manufacture of sorghum beer. JJIZ Table 5-22: Characteristics of rural households by net sales position IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII Pct Farm food Home Pct Expend Nbr size self Kca] Sales Purch prod hh (F/ae) pers (ha) suff /ae (kg) (kg) (kg) Net sales of sorghum < -100 kg 16.0 13,551 5.3 1.5 66 2,502 3 292 10 -100 to -50 kg 9.3 13,933 4.6 .7 71 2,709 4 73 7 -50 to -1 kg 25.6 13,313 5.0 1.1 67 2,473 4 30 8 0 kg 24.5 11,907 3.9 1.1 64 2,279 0 O 4 1 to 100 kg 13.6 11,857 5.7 1.6 70 2,262 53 15 11 > 100 kg 10.9 15,418 5.9 2.1 74 2,659 268 32 14 Net sales of cassava < -100 kg 9.9 11,597 6.0 1.1 61 2,135 5 194 217 -100 to -50 kg 5.9 9,651 5.6 1.1 54 1,872 13 82 186 -50 to -1 kg 16.6 13,212 4.5 .9 65 2.523 4 26 173 0 kg 44.1 13,933 4.5 1.4 71 2,622 0 0 141 1 to 100 kg 10.0 14,415 5.0 1.4 68 2,244 62 7 419 > 100 kg 13.5 11,833 5.6 1.6 70 2,387 402 7 520 Net sales of sweet potatoes < -100 kg 12.9 10,799 6.1 1.4 67 2,092 3 306 905 -100 to -50 kg 7.9 10,049 5.4 1.3 71 2,210 0 77 685 -50 to -1 kg 6.5 14,478 5.5 1.0 65 2,480 0 24 494 0 kg 48.4 13,651 4.6 1.3 67 2,497 0 0 624 1 to 100 kg 9.8 14,313 4.8 1.4 66 2,471 84 9 757 > 100 kg 14.4 13,514 4.6 1.2 70 2,671 387 0 1,457 Net sales of white potatoes < -100 kg 8.7 13,701 5.9 1.5 59 2,435 2 141 75 -100 to ~50 kg 8.8 14,458 5.5 1.3 70 2.558 1 71 60 -50 to -1 kg 15.7 14,691 4.9 1.3 69 2,509 l 30 47 0 kg 53.9 12,020 4.7 1.3 67 2,344 0 0 43 1 to 100 kg 3.7 12,263 5.4 1.1 73 2,519 71 9 793 > 100 kg 9.3 15,111 5.0 1.3 71 2,782 865 4 1,137 Net sales of bananas < -100 kg 9.3 15,466 5.9 1.0 59 2,386 1 664 580 -100 to -50 kg 5.4 9,997 5.4 1.3 65 2,283 19 91 353 -50 to -1 kg 8.7 13,792 5.0 1.2 60 2,430 5 21 297 0 kg 45.1 11,907 4.7 1.2 68 2,380 0 0 208 1 to 100 kg 9.5 11,797 4.6 1.0 65 2,503 72 20 454 > 100 kg 22.0 15,582 5.0 1.8 74 2,617 488 32 1,294 Net sales of beans . < -100 kg 18.8 11,814 6.1 1.5 59 2,281 8 176 315 -100 to -50 kg 17.8 11,751 5.2 1.2 68 2,381 5 77 303 -50 to -1 kg 33.3 13,356 4.4 .9 68 2,504 6 30 291 0 kg 9.3 13,241 4.2 1.5 63 2,260 0 O 251 1 to 100 kg 15.2 13,098 4.8 1.7 75 2,539 54 15 450 > 100 kg 5.6 19,923 4.9 1.9 72 2,881 150 S 553 Sales of coffee 0 kg 67.2 13,354 4.7 1.2 68 2,593 0 0 0 1 to 100 kg 30.0 12,296 5.3 1.4 66 2,138 35 0 0 > 100 kg 2.8 15,427 6.9 1.8 68 2,143 205 0 0 Rura] means 100.0 13,095 4.9 1.3 67 2,444 115 77 520 143 expenditure and caloric intake. The characteristics of net buyers are explained by the fact that potatoes are a relatively costly source of calories. Concerning the net position in bananas, large-scale net buyers are relatively well off, in spite of the small average farm size and low level of food self-sufficiency. As in the case of sorghum, this is probably due to the presence of important banana beer producers among the net buyers. Large-scale net sellers are also relatively well-off, although they tend to have above average farm sizes and rates of food self-sufficiency. Beans present the clearest case in which net sales are correlated with the level of expenditure per adult equivalent, caloric intake, and food self-sufficiency. Households buying over 50 kg/yr do not have particularly small farms, but they are larger in number than the average rural household. Finally, Table 5-22 seems to indicate that ”large-scale" coffee growers (those selling over 100 kg/yr) are better off than the average rural household in terms of expenditure (though not in terms of caloric intake), but small-scale coffee growers are less well off. This is plausible, but the sample size for the ”large-scale" growers is too (small to draw firm conclusions. Interestingly, the rate of food self- sufficiency is the same between growers and non-growers. 5.5.3 Tpadeable component of expenditure and income In this section, we concentrate on the composition of cash expenditure and cash income with particular emphasis on the tradeable and nontradeable components. As discussed in section 4.5.2, the rural budget survey used a system of 405 codes for goods and services, while the urban survey relied on an even more disaggregated system of 825 codes. Each code was classified as tradeable or non- tradeable, based on a judgement as to whether the domestic price is determined by international prices or by domestic supply and demand. 144 Tradeable goods include export crops, rice, cooking oil, wheat products, sugar, processed foods, and most manufactured consumer items. Host staple food crops, building materials, and other bulky low-value products were considered non-tradeable, as were all services. As discussed earlier, factory beer is considered 50% tradeable, while beans are counted as 25% tradeable (see Appendix A). Table 5-23 gives the proportion of tradeable goods in cash expenditure on each budget category. For example, tradeable goods account for 16% of rural cash expenditure on food, but tradeables represent almost twice as high a percentage of urban cash food expenditure (30%). Part of this difference is due to the fact that non- tradeable categories, such as tubers/bananas, play a larger role in the cash budget of rural households than urban. In addition, the composition of each category is more heavily weighted toward tradeable goods in the urban sector, particularly in the case of grains, animal products, and beverages. With respect to grains, rural households purchase primarily (nontradeable) sorghum and maize, while urban households buy mostly (tradeable) rice and wheat products. With regard to beverages, the differences is due to the fact that factory beer is much more important in the cities. Non-tradeable traditional beers dominate beverage purchases in the countryside. Among-non-food categories, rural cash expenditure has a larger tradeable component (57%) than does urban cash expenditure (47%). This is primarily due to the composition of energy/water, education, and leisure/services. In general terms, this is because urban spending is more concentrated on services (e.g. water, electricity, school fees, and leisure services), while rural spending tends to have a larger share of goods, including tradeable goods (e.g. kerosene, school uniforms, and consumer goods). In addition, a much larger share of rural non-food _spending is allocated to clothing, which is almost entirely tradeable. 145 Table 5-23: Tradeable component of rural and urban cash expenditure IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-Il Budget category Rural Urban We). 36.6 39.2 Food 16.0 29.6 Grain 36.1 85.9 Tubers/bananas .0 .0 Legumes 23.0 22.2 Fruits/vegetables 1.0 4.5 Animal products 2.2 17.9 Beverages 7.3 37.7 Other 47.0 52.3 Non-food sub-total 56.9 47.3 Clothing 96.4 94.0 Housing 14.1 15.7 Household equipment 64.2 76.2 Energy/water 82.1 26.8 Health/hygiene - 50.4 72.9 Education 33.7 15.5 Transportation 51.2 84.0 Tobacco ' .0 .0 Leisure/services 50.7 29.8 Interestingly, the tradeable share in overall spending is almost the same in rural and urban areas (37% and 39%, respectively). This is somewhat surprising given the conventional wisdom that imported goods play a much larger role in urban (and high-income) household budgets. If the prices of all tradeable goods increase in the same proportion, which price increases will have the greatest effect on household budgets? In order to address this question, we need to examine the composition of tradeable goods spending, as shown in Table 5-24. The most striking aspect of this table is that almost half (46%) of all tradeable goods spending in the rural sector is on clothing. The ENBC data indicate that imported used clothing accounts for roughly one third of rural clothing expenditure. Bolts of cloth and African print wraps, also imported for the most part, represents another third (see Ministry of Planning, 1988: 33). Household equipment and "other food" represent the second and third largest categories of rural tradeable spending. Each of these 146 Table 5-24: Composition of rural and urban tradeable cash expenditure IIIIIIIIIIIIIImIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIImIIImum-IIIIIIIII-Imuuummmma Budget category Rural Urban ’ 56ml 100.0 100.0 Food 21.6 34.5 Grain 3.3 9.7 Tubers/bananas .0 .0 Legumes 5.9 2.5 Fruits/vegetables .0 .3 Animal products .4 3.6 Beverages 3.4 9.5 Other 8.5 8.9 Non-food 78.4 65.5 Clothing 46.2 13.9 Housing 5.5 7.5 Household equipment 8.7 7.5 Energy/water 5.4 3.9 Health/hygiene 5.8 6.4 Education 1.0 .6 Transportation 44.3' 23.2 Tobacco .0 .0 Leisure/services 1.5 2.5 categories accounts for 8-9% of tradeable spending. In the urban areas, transportation represents almost one quarter (23%) of tradeable spending. This includes taxi and bus fare, fuel, spare parts, and lubricants, but bus fares represent almost half of the total. Other important components of tradeable spending are grains (wheat products and rice) and beverages (primarily factory beer). Having discussed the tradeable component in the average budget of rural and urban households, it is now worth examining how the tradeable component varies across households. Tables 5-25 and 5-26 give the proportion of cash expenditure and of net cash income which is associated with tradeable goods in the rural and urban sectors, respectively. According to Table 5-25, the tradeable portion of rural cash expenditure does not show any consistent pattern with respect to total expenditure, although it is highest for the third quintile. The net cash income pattern is only somewhat more regular, with a "peak” in the second and third quintiles. This peak corresponds to a larger number of 147 coffee producers in the third quintile, although this may be merely a characteristic of the sample. Table 5-25: Importance of tradeables in rural income and expenditure by expenditure quintile Tradeable share Tradeable share Rural in cash in cash net quintile expenditure (%) income (%) lat 36.9 7.3 2nd 35.9 ' 17.0 3rd 42.4 20.5 4th 38.8 . 7.5 5th ‘ 32.1 8.2 Table 5-26 gives the corresponding results for the urban sector. The importance of tradeable goods in urban cash expenditures rises from 31% in the first (poorest) quintile to over 40% in the last two quintiles. The pattern for net income is irregular, but it appears that the poorest 40% in the urban sector rely primarily on non-tradeable types of income. This would indicate that the urban poor would be hurt by devaluation, in spite of their relatively low spending on tradeables, because of their overwhelmingly non-tradeable sources of income. ls 148 Table 5-26: Importance of tradeables in urban income and expenditure by expenditure quintile Tradeable share Tradeable share Urban in cash in cash net quintile expenditure (%) income (%) 1st 31.1 5.6 ‘2nd 34.7 5.7 3rd 36.8 30.3 4th 43.6 16.2 5th 40.2 22.1 The results in Tables 5-25 and 5-26 should be regarded with some skepticism. It should be recalled that in the rural areas, cash transactions are modest in absolute terms and may be greatly influenced by a single large transaction. In addition, net income is subject to greater measurement error than expenditure, a fact which is more serious when the data are disaggregated. Finally, the classification of income sources into tradeable and nontradeable groups is more difficult than the classification of expenditure. 5.5.4 §ppmgpy With regard to the impact of price changes on Rwandan households, three topics were examined: the importance of market transactions within the overall budget, the net sales position with respect to the principal crops, and the tradeable component of cash income and expenditure. The importance of market purchases in total expenditure is positively related to the level of expenditure per adult equivalent in both rural and urban areas. As a result of these patterns, we can expect a given price change to have an effect on urban households at least twice as great as that on rural households. Furthermore, other 149 things being equal, the impact will be fairly similar across rural households, but it will vary considerably among urban households. The net sales information indicate that the rural sector of Rwanda purchases more beans than it sells, implying the existence of informal imports. Almost three quarters of the rural households are net buyers. The data also imply the existence of sorghum imports. For the other staple food crops, as a rule of thumb, price increases will benefit the 25% of rural households who are net sellers, harm another quarter of the households, and leave unaffected the remaining 50% of rural households who do not have market transactions in that commodity. A household with net sales in one commodity shows no significant tendency to have net sales in other commodities. In the case of beans and possibly cassava and sweet potatoes, net purchases are correlated with reduced caloric intake and expenditure levels. The proportion of cash expenditure spent on tradeable good is roughly the same in rural and urban sectors. In the rural sector, clothing accounts for almost half of cash expenditure on tradeables, while transportation is the most important type of tradeable spending among urban households. The tradeable share in cash expenditure is greater among high-income urban households than low-income, but it shows no strong trend in the rural sector. Thus, the impact of devaluation is expected to be less among rural households and among the poor, not because they purchase fewer tradeables, but because purchases are a smaller part of their overall expenditure. However, these results are only suggestive in that the analysis has not combined the various factors into one welfare measure, nor does the analysis incorporate the adaptation of households as consumers and as producers. This is the task of the next two chapters. CHAPTER SIX MODEL OF HOUSEHOLD DEMAND In this section, we describe the results of the estimation of rural and urban food demand as a function of total expenditure (income), household characteristics, and prices. Sections 6.1 describes several aspects of model selection: whether to estimate separate rural and urban models or combine them, what commodity categories to use, and whether single-equation ordinary least squares (OLS) or the seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) model is more appropriate.. Sections 6.2 and 6.3 describe the results of the rural model with and without imposing symmetry, while 6.4 and 6.5 provide the corresponding results from the urban model. The final two sections digress somewhat to cover two topics: 1) a comparison of OLS and Tobit results in estimating rural food demand and 2) an analysis of the possible influence of quality and measurement error in the elasticity estimates. 6.1 e ect o the a ro 'a e model 6.1.1 tme o a a d ba sam e The first question to address is whether urban consumer behavior is sufficiently different from rural behavior to justify separating urban and rural samples to estimate demand from each. Statistically, the question is whether there are variables missing from the demand equations (such as tastes and assets) which vary between rural and urban households and are correlated with the independent variables, thus biasing the combined-sample parameter estimates. We can use the F test (see equation 4-16) to statistically test the joint null hypothesis that all rural coefficients are equal to the corresponding urban coefficients (this is also called a Chow test). The test is carried out equation-by-equation using ordinary least squares. 150 151 Table 6-1: Test of equality of urban and rural coefficients Category F stat Prob The results in Table 6-1 indicate that, at the 90% confidence soaca 1.41 0.10 arcs 1.17 0.27 SWPOT 3.67 0.00 wspor 3.03 0.00 BANAN 5.43 0.00 BEANS 2.67 0.00 PEAS 1.46 0.09 sass 1.57 0.05 _ MEAT 1.72 0.02 asses 1.46 0.09 ssEBR 3.99 0.00 FBEER 1.33 0.15 OIL 1.64 0.04 . SALT 1.66 0.03 SUGAR 1.67 0.03 cross 2.06 0.06 30083 0.59 0.74 EQUIP 0.26 0.96 4 snsac 14.33 0.00 - HEALT 6.16 0.00 EDUCA 1.67 0.13 TRANS 4.30 0.00 TOBAC 8.89 0.00 LEISU 8.12 0.00 level, we can reject the null hypothesis that rural and urban coeffi- cients are equal for 20 out of the 24 budget categories tested. Only in the equations for rice, housing, education, and household equipment are the differences statistically insignificant at the 90% level. At the 95% level, we can reject the hypothesis of rural-urban equality for 16 out of the 24 equations (sorghum, peas, banana beer, and clothing). Taking the commodities as a group, it is clear that urban and rural coefficients are significantly different. Thus, it is appropriate to estimate separately rural and urban demand. 6.1.2 Commodity categories Twenty-one food categories were considered for inclusion in the rural model. The F statistic was used to test the joint null 152 hypothesis that all the coefficients (other than the constant) were equal to zero. The hypothesis could not be rejected for several minor commodities. After some experimentation, it was decided to drop four goods from the rural model (eggplant, cabbage, onion, and prepared meals) and to combine goat meat and fish into an "other meat" category. The price of ”other meat” was calculated as the weighted average of goat and fish prices. The impact of these changes is relatively minor since the four dropped goods account for only 1.7% of rural expenditures, while ”other meat" represents 1.8%. The 17 food commodities included in the rural model are presented in Table 6—2. On average, they represent 74% of household expenditure and 87% of household food expenditure among rural households. In the urban system, 26 food products were originally included. Based on the F-test of the joint significance of the independent variables, it was decided to combine four vegetables (eggplant, cabbage, tomatoes, and onions) into a "vegetables" category, to combine goat meat and fish into "other meat," and to collapse liquid and powder milk categories. Again, the prices of the combined categories were calculat- ed as a weighted average of the various components of each. The 21 food commodities in the urban model are briefly described in Table 6-2. On average, they comprise about 59% of total expenditure and 90% of food expenditure by households. The greater coverage of food expenditure in the urban model is due to the inclusion of three catego- ries not in the rural model: bread, milk, and prepared meals. Other differences are that the urban model disaggregates cassava into cassava root and cassava flour and that it includes the category "vegetables," while the rural model has just "tomatoes." In both the rural and urban models, non-food expenditure was divided into nine categories for the purpose of demand estimation. Although the joint significance of the independent variables was low for some non-food categories, all nine were retained in the final model to 153 Table 6-2: Description of food products in rural and urban models _ Food Rural Urban Description Code model model SORGH Yes Yes Sorghum in grain or porridge RICE Yes Yes Rice in grain or other form BREAD No Yes Bread, cake, or other wheat product CASSA Yes Yes Cassava root and, in rural model, cassava flour SWPOT Yes Yes Sweet potato WHPOT Yes Yes White potato BANAN Yes Yes Bananas and plantains CASFL No Yes Cassava flour BEANS Yes Yes Dry beans in any form PEAS Yes ‘ Yes Peas TOMAT Yes No Fresh tomatoes VEGET No Yes Cabbage, onion, tomato, & eggplant BEEF . Yes Yes Beef and related products‘ OTHMT Yes Yes Goat meat or any type of fish MILK No Yes Liquid milk or milk powder BBEER Yes Yes Banana beer SBEER Yes Yes Sorghum beer FBEER Yes Yes Factory beer OIL Yes Yes Palm oil, other oils and fats SALT Yes Yes Salt SUGAR Yes Yes Sugar, candy, and other sweets MEALS No Yes Prepared meals outside home OTHER No No Millet, yams, groundnuts, greens, other vegetables, fruit, other meat, other beverages, canned or processed goods allow finer disaggregation between tradeable and nontradeable goods. Table 6-3 provides a brief description of the goods and services which comprise each non—food category. 6.1.3 Efipiggpigp_m§thod: OLS vg SUR As described in Chapter 4, there are two situations in which the seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) model does not improve on the estimates obtained from single-equation ordinary least squares (OLS): 1) when all the equations in the model have the same independent variables and 2) when there is no correlation among errors in different equations. The first condition is not fulfilled because the food equations have price terms while the non-food equations do not. The 154 Table 6-3: Description of non-food categories in rural and urban models — Rural Urban Category model model Description CLOTH ‘Yes Yes Clothing, shoes, hats, accessories, cloth, sewing materials, tailor services HOUSE Yes Yes Building materials, construction labor (excludes rent and the purchase of buildings and land) EQUIP ‘Yes Yes Furniture, kitchenware, bedding, floor mats, decorations ENERG ‘Yes Yes Firewood, charcoal, water, kerosene, electricity, batteries HEALT , Yes Yes Medication, clinic fees, traditional healers EDUCA Yes Yes School fees, school uniforms, school materials TRANS ‘Yes Yes Buses, taxis, spare parts, operating cost of vehicles (excludes purchase of vehicles) TOBAC ‘Yes Yes Cigarettes, tobacco leaf, tobacco powder LEISU ‘Yes Yes Radios, cassettes, games, sporting equipment, domestic employees second condition can be tested using the Breush-Pagan test of diagon- ality. The first step in the test is to estimate food and non-food demand using single-equation OLS regression. The residuals are then used to estimate the covariance matrix of errors across equations and within households. The Breush-Pagan statistic tests the null hypothesis that the covariance matrix is diagonal (i.e. that there is no correlation in the error terms across equations). The Breusch-Pagan test of the 26x26 cross-equation covariance matrix of the rural model indicates that we can reject the null hypothe- sis of diagonality at the 99.9% confidence level. Null hypothesis: Cross-equation covariance matrix of residuals is diagonal in rural model. Chi squared - 762.845 with d.f.= 325 Prob under Ho - 0.000 he. 38: 301 $91 155 In the presence of cross-equation correlation of error terms, the SUR model is more efficient than single-equation OLS because it uses information regarding the correlated error terms to improve the parame- ter estimates. The Breusch-Pagan test was also applied to the 30x30 cross- equation covariance matrix of the urban model. Again, the chi-squared statistic was quite high, allowing us to reject the hypothesis of , diagonality at the 99.9% confidence level. Null hypothesis: Cross-equation covariance matrix of residuals is diagonal in urban model. Chi squared = 1572.461 with d.f.= 435 Prob under Ho - 0.000 Thus, the SUR model is more appropriate for the urban demand system as well. It should be noted, however, that in spite of the non-diagonality of the cross-equation covariance matrix, the parameter estimates obtained using SUR are quite similar to those obtained using OLS. For example, the expenditure and price elasticities at the mean differ by 0.02 or less for almost every food category. In the case of non-food categories, OLS and SUR estimates are identical because the non-food equations exclude prices and are thus over-identified. If the computa- tional costs of SUR were high, single-equation OLS would be sufficiently accurate for most purposes. 6.2 Unpestpicped SUR model of rurgl demand The unrestricted SUR model of rural demand involves the simulta- neous estimation of 445 parameters (six coefficients common to all 26 equation, plus 17 price terms in each of the 17 food equations). Because of the large number of coefficients and because many of them are not easily interpretable in original form, this section presents only selected results. A complete listing of the coefficients and their corresponding t statistics is found in Appendix C. 156 First, overall measures of the goodness-of-fit and significance of the equations are discussed. Then, we consider the impact of different groups of independent variables: the two expenditure terms, the three household composition variables, and the price terms. 6.2.1 Overal oodness- f- t and si n cance 1 Table 6-4 presents the mean budget share , the correla- tion coefficient (R2), the F statistic for the equation as a whole, and E the probability corresponding to the F statistic.. The correlation : coefficient indicates the proportion of the variance in the dependent E variable (budget share) which is."exp1ained” by the set of independent variables. The value of R2 varies from 0.01 for three non-food catego- - E ries (health, tobacco, and leisure/services) to 0.39 for sweet potatoes. Although these values may seem low, this is normal for cross-sectional - demand studies, particularly when budget share, rather than quantity, is the dependent variable. The values of the correlation coefficient are generally higher for food categories than for non-food categories. The low correlation coefficients of non-food regression equations reflects the smaller number of independent variables (six compared to 23 in the food equa- tions). In addition, non-food expenditure is probably less predictable than food expenditure because the budget shares are small and the purchases are often lumpy and infrequent. For example, a single 5 20 radio would represent ten times the mean expenditure per household on leisure and services. The F statistic in Table 6-4 tests the hypothesis that all coefficients except the constant are equal to zero. In other words, the 1. These budget shares do not agree exactly with those presented in Chapter 5 because of different calculation methods. First, these are unweighted averages, whereas the figures in Chapter 5 use the expansion factors based on the sampling method. Second, these figures are averages shares, while the figures in Chapter 5 represent the share of total expenditure allocated to each category. The latter figures give more weight to high-expenditure households. 157 Table 6-4: Summary of unrestricted SUR model of rural demand — Mean F stat Prob Budget budget for all under category share R2 variab Ho SORGH 1.41 0.16 2.28 0.00 RICE 0.49 0.10 1.24 0.19 CASSA 5.92 0.13 1.65 0.03 SWPOT 12.54 0.39 7.93 0.00 WHPOT 4.02 0.30 4.82 0.00 BANAN 5.86 0.34 5.87 0.00 BEANS 21.61 0.28 4.25 0.00 PEAS 1.39 0.12 1.59 0.04 TOMAT 0.13 0.15 1.94 0.00 BEEF 1.39 0.14 1.87 0.01 MEAT 1.91 0.14 1.95 0.00 BBEER ” 10.15 -0.17 2.49 0.00 SBEER 3.91 0.21 3.29 0.00 FBEER 0.80 0.20 3.07 0.00 OIL 0.96 0.20 2.97 0.00 SALT 1.02 0.18 2.81 0.00 SUGAR 0.31 0.12 1.76 0.01 CLOTH 6.30 0.06 3.37 0.00 HOUSE 3.31 0.18 10.87 0.00 EQUIP 1.54 0.04 2.08 0.05 ENERG 1.19 0.03 1.58 0.15 HEALT 1.68 0.01 0.52 0.79 EDUCA 0.42 0.03 1.44 0.20 TRANS 0.80 0.07 3.64 0.00 TOBAC 0.71 0.01 0.73 0.63 LEISU 0.36 0.01 0.67 0.67 null hypothesis is that the budget share does not vary with total expenditure, price, or household composition. The last column gives the probability of obtaining the corresponding value of F if the null hypothesis is true. The results show that the null hypothesis can be rejected at the 95% confidence level for 20 of the 26 equations (17 of these are significant at the 99% level). Rice is the only food commodi— ty for which the coefficients are not significantly different from zero at the 95% level. This category, which represents only 0.5 % of the rural budget, was retained because it is one of a few tradeable foods and thus will be important in subsequent analysis. clc car all wit are sha ODE as e The Easy (T189 EXPQ at a gene Dace QCCU' is ‘31/1 fOun e 158 Among the non-food categories, the budget shares allocated to clothing, housing, household equipment, and transportation vary signifi- cantly with the five independent variables. In contrast, the shares allocated to the other non-food categories do not vary significantly with the independent variables. Health, tobacco, and leisure/services are the least predictable budget categories. 6-2-2 W Engel's Law states that, as income rises, the budget share of food in general, and starchy staple foods in particular, falls. In other words, food should have an expenditure elasticity less than one, and the cheapest sources of calories should have the lowest elasticities. Table 6-5 presents the average cost (in Rwandan francs of 1983) per 100 kilocalories of the most important foods. This table demonstrates that sorghum, sweet potato, cassava, and bananas are the least expensive sources of calories. Rice, white potatoes, and banana beer are at least twice as costly on a per calorie basis, but are still considerably less expensive than beef, goat meat, and factory beer. The impact of total household expenditure on rural budget shares, as estimated with the unrestricted SUR model, is shown in Table 6-6. The estimated coefficients on the expenditure terms, 81 and 82, are not easy to interpret by themselves. If both 81 and 82 have positive (negative) signs then budget share increases (decreases) with total expenditure, so the item is a luxury good (necessity or inferior good) at all levels of income. When 81 and 82 have different signs, as is generally the case, goods may change from luxury to necessity (or necessity to luxury) as household expenditure increasesl. 1. The transition from luxury to necessity (or vice versa) occurs when the budget share curve reaches a maximum (or minimum), that is, when the expenditure elasticity is 1.0. At this point, log(x/P) 8 -81/282. If 8i and 82 have different signs, then the extremum will be found at a positive level of expenditure, but it may still be outside the relevant range. 159 Table 6-5: Caloric cost of various food items _ Calories Price Caloric cost Product (kcal/100 g) (F/kg) (F/100 kcal) SORGH 345 20.9 0.61 RICE 363 80.4 2.21 CASSA 130 10.5 0.81 SWPOT 96 6.0 0.63 WHPOT 71 12.9 1.82 BANAN 89 7.3 0.83 BEANS 323 29.6 0.92 PEAS 339 35.5 1.05 TOMAT 20 24.2 12.10 BEEF 237 116.8 4.93 GOAT 141 113.5 8.05 BBEER 87 30.5 3.51 SBEER 173 14.1 0.82 FBEER 43 123.7 28.77 OIL 884 154.9 1.75 SALT 0 “47.0 not defined SUGAR 380 97.3 2.56 The elasticity of demand with respect to total household expendi- ture is easier to interpret. These elasticities are calculated from 81 and 8? using the following expression (derived in section 4.3.4): 61 = 1 + .911 + _2912 ln(i‘) (6-1) w, 83 P The rural expenditure elasticities of demand for food were evaluated at the mean level of expenditure and are presented in the fifth column of Table 6-6. The sixth column provides the F statistic for the null hypothesis that 81=Bz=0. Under the null hypothesis, budget share does not vary with household expenditure, so that the expenditure elasticity is equal to 1.0 at all levels of expenditure. The last column of Table 6-6 gives the probability of obtaining this value of F by chance if the null hypothesis is true. The food elasticities conform, in general, to a priori expecta- tions. First, the expenditure elasticity of food as a whole is 0.85 (this is calculated as the share-weighted average of individual elastic- 160 Table 6-6: Effect of household expenditure on rural demand — ln(exp) F stat Prob Budget ln(exp) sqrd expend for under category 81 t 82 t elast expend Ho SORGH -16.19 -1.75 0.79 1.69 0.48 3.02 0.05 RICE 5.79 0.89 -0.28 -0.84 1.80 1.48 0.23 CASSA 22.14 0.69 -1.30 ~0.80 0.45 5.24 0.01 .SWPOT -98.44 -2.64 4.41 2.33 0.02 40.99 0.00 WHPOT 68.33 2.33 -3.33 -2.24 1.83 5.95 0.00 BANAN -15.77 -0.52 0.82 0.54 1.04 0.21 0.81 BEANS 70.83 1.47 -4.03 -1.65 0.63 14.99 0.00 PEAS 11.62 0.86 -0.59 -0.86 1.09 0.37 0.69 TOMAT 0.20 0.11 -0.01 -0.13 0.70 0.20 0.82 BEEF -1.14 -0.12 0.11 0.22 1.66 4.10 0.02 MEAT 7.48 0.39 -0.30 -0.32 1.80 2.53 0.08 BBEER 4.32 0.11 -0.04 -0.02 1.34 2.97 0.05 SBEER 26.46 1.18 -1.30 -1.15 1.25 1.09 0.34 FBEER -15.23 -1.39 0.86 1.54 2.85 10.49 0.00 OIL 10.71 1.58 -0.52 -1.52 1.58 2.96 '0.05 SALT 3.55 0.99 -0.20 -1.13 0.56 8.22 0.00 SUGAR 3.55 0.71 -0.16 -0.64 2.24 2.23 0.11 CLOTH 2.63 0.12 -0.09 -0.08 1.15 0.80 0.45 HOUSE -92.54 -2.95 5.04 3.17 2.77 26.07 0.00 EQUIP 6.74 0.39 -0.25 -0.29 2.17 4.68 0.01 ENERG 1.69 0.18 -0.10 -0.21 0.72 0.61 0.55 HEALT 3.30 0.37 -0.17 -0.38 0.96 0.12 0.88 EDUCA 4.30 0.62 -0.21 -0.61 1.25 0.22 0.80 TRANS -5.33 -0.64 0.33 0.78 2.35 8.52 0.00 TOBAC -0.41 -0.08 0.01 0.05 0.80 0.31 0.74 LEISU 3.34 0.47 -0.15 -0.42 1.97 0.96 0.38 ities). In other words, a 1% increase in total household expenditure is associated with a 0.85% rise in food expenditure. This implies, of course, that food is a "necessity" and that the budget share allocated to food declines with increasing total expenditure. In addition, the highest expenditure elasticity (2.85) is that of factory beer, the most expensive source of calories among the products considered: compared to traditional beers, it is seven times as expen- sive on a calorie basis and four times as costly on a volume basis. Other foods with elasticities significantly greater than 1.0 are beef, white potatoes, banana beer, and cooking oil, all relatively expensive sources of calories in Rwanda (the elasticities of rice, other meat, and sugar are also high, but are not significantly greater than 1.0). in t1: C8 161 By contrast, the three cheapest sources of calories (sorghum, sweet potatoes, and cassava) have expenditure elasticities below 0.5; all three are significantly less than 1.0. Beans and salt also qualify as "necessities“ with elasticities significantly less than 1.0. It is worth noting that, at the mean expenditure level in the rural areas, there are no inferior goods. Sweet potatoes come the closest to being inferior with an expenditure elasticity of 0.02. This means that, at the mean level of expenditure, sweet potato expenditures remain practi- cally constant as total household expenditure rises. Among the non-food categories, the highest expenditure elastici- ties are those of housing (2.77), transportation (2.35), and household equipment (2.17). Although the expenditure terms in these three equations are significant at the 99% confidence level, none of the other non-food equations has statistically significant expenditure coeffi- cients. In other words, we cannot reject the hypothesis that rural budget shares are constant across income for the other six non-food categories. Looking at both food and non-food categories in Table 6-6, the F test indicates that the two expenditure terms are jointly significant at the 95% level in 13 of the 26 equations. A cross-equation test of all 52 expenditure coefficients in the rural model yields an F statistic of 5.4, which is significant at the 99% confidence level. Thus, we can reject the null hypothesis that rural budget shares are constant across household expenditure levels. The t statistic on the quadratic term, 32, is significant at the 95% level in only three equations (sweet potatoes, white potatoes, and housing) and at the 90% level for two more (sorghum and beans)‘. A cross-equation test of the joint significance of all 26 quadratic terms 1. The critical value of the t statistic with 246 degrees of freedom at the two-tailed 95% confidence level is 1.96. At the two- tailed 90% level, the critical value is 1.65. 162 rejects the null hypothesis only at the 90% level. When the test is restricted to the 17 food equations within the system, the quadratic terms are significantly different from zero at the 99% confidence level. This result indicates that using the standard AIDS (without the quadrat- ic term) to model demand in rural Rwanda would not allow sufficient flexibility in the relationship between food budget share and total expenditure (income). 6.2.3 Effect of household composition 7 The three demographic variables are the number of adults, the number of children, and a dummy variable to indicate a female-headed household. The first two demographic coefficients (71 and 72) in Table 6-7 indicate the effect on budget share of each additional member of the household, holding prices and real expenditure per adult-equivalent - constant. The third demographic coefficient (73) shows the change in budget share associated with a female-headed household. Few of the demographic variables are statistically significant in the rural demand model, as indicated by the t-statistics in Table 6-7. Only seven of the 81 demographic coefficients are statistically signifi- cant at the 95% confidence level and nine more are significant at the 90% level. The coefficients associated with household size (71 and 72) which are significant at the 90% level provide weak support for the hypothesis of "economies of scale" in household size. In this case, large house- holds with the Same expenditure per adult equivalent consume more luxuries (oil, sugar, other meat, and housing) and relatively less of the necessities (sweet potatoes, beans, salt, and energy). This is a common pattern in household budget data and is generally attributed to economies of scale in non-food consumption such as housing (see Deaton and Case, 1987). Not surprisingly, the number of children is negatively associated with the budget share allocated to tobacco. Contrary to expectations, 163 Table 6-7: Effect of household composition on rural demand number number female Budget adults children head category 71 t 72 t 73 t sofics* -0.04 -0.31 0.00 0.04 -0.37 -1.12 RICE -0.05 -0.63 0.08 1.44 0.40 1.75 CASSA -0.18 -0.46 -0.07 -0.23 0.56 0.49 SWPOT -0.84 -1.78 -0.25 -0.74 0.88 0.66 WHPOT 0.20 0.55 0.30 1.13 0.12 0.11 BANAN 0.09 0.24 0.16 0.59 0.93 0.87 m BEANS -l.66 -2.73 -0.85 -1.95 1.47 0.86 i PEAS -0.17 -1.00 -0.12 -0.99 -0.24 -0.50 ' TOMAT -0.02 -0.67 0.01 0.56 0.09 1.39 BEEF 0.09 0.78 0.04 0.47 0.28 0.83 MEAT -0.10 -0.43 0.35 2.04 -1.11 -1.64 I BBEER 0.15 ' 0.29 -0.37 -1.00 -4;62 -3.20 7 SBEER 0.42 1.47 -0.11 -0.57 -0.61 -0.77 FBEER 0.07 0.54 0.03 0.33 -0.58 -1.48 OIL 0.15 1.71 0.05 0.83 -0.25 -1.04 SALT -0.10 -2.20 -0.05 -1.54 -0.05 -0.36 F SUGAR 0.05 0.75 0.08 1.72 0.17 0.94 ' CLOTH 0.93 3.46 -0.37 -1.93 -0.02 -0.03 HOUSE 0.74 1.90 0.82 2.93 1.55 1.41 EQUIP 0.08 0.39 0.12 0.80 -0.38 -0.62 ENERG -0.07 -0.61 -0.23 -2.62 -0.11 -0.32 HEALT 0.15 1.37 -0.06 -0.74 0.03 0.11 EDUCA 0.14 1.60 0.10 1.62 -0.03 -0.10 TRANS -0.03 -0.31 0.09 1.14 0.21 0.73 TOBAC 0.03 0.43 -0.08 —1.73 -0.19 -1.01 LEISU -0.03 -0.28 0.02 0.31 -0.25 -0.99 — the number of children is not significantly related to the portion of the budget.allocated to beer. Perhaps the fact that children consume less beer is offset by the economies of household size since beer is a ”luxury.” With regard to the impact of children on education spending, although the sign is correct (positive), the coefficient is not quite significant at the 90% confidence level. Testing the cross-equation hypothesis that the numbers of adults and of children do not affect budget shares in the rural sector (1427220), the F statistic indicates that we can reject the hypothesis at the 99% level of confidence. In other words, budget shares in the 164 rural sector are influenced by the number of adults and children in the household, holding other variables constant. . The sex of the head of household is represented by a dummy variable which takes the value 1 for a female head and 0 for a male head. At the 95% confidence level, the results show that female-headed households allocate a significantly smaller portion of their budget (4.6 percentage points less) to banana beer. This finding probably reflects social norms against banana beer consumption by women. By contrast, sorghum beer is considered more appropriate for women (see Haggblade, 1988). _ If we accept a 90% confidence level, then female-headed household allocate a somewhat larger share of the budget to rice and a smaller share to ”other meat" (goat and fish). The former result may be related‘ to the greater time pressure of female heads and the ease of rice preparation compared to alternative staples. It should be noted, however, that rice constitutes a very minor portion of the budget (less than 1%) in rural households, regardless of the gender of the household head. The weak tendency of female headed households to consume less of ”other meat” may be due to traditional beliefs that discourage women from consuming goat meatl. Testing the cross-equation hypothesis that the sex of head of household does not affect budget allocations (y3=0 in all equations), the F statistic indicates that we can reject the null hypothesis only at the 90% confidence level. Further analysis reveals that the gender of the head of household is a significant determinant of food allocations but that it does not influence non-food budget shares. 1. A common belief in Rwanda is that eating goat meat contributes to facial hair in women. 165 6.2.4 Effect of prices The effect of food prices on the demand for food is estimated directly as part of the SUR model. Non-food price effects are not estimated but derived under the assumptions of strongly separable preferences. The results of each procedure are discussed in turn. Estimated food price elasticities: The estimated price parameter, a“, represents the compensated effect of the log of the F price of food item j on the budget share of food item i. The interpre- , tation of these coefficients is complicated by the fact that even if a Q price increase in good j does not affect the budget share of good i (i.e. mU-O), the compensated demand will increase slightly due to the i adjustment in nominal income to maintain a constant real incomel. i Because the coefficients cannot be directly interpreted, they are relegated to Appendix C, and we will move directly to the discussion of price elasticities. The uncompensated (Marshallian) price elasticities are calculated from the estimated parameters using the following equation (derived in section 4.3.4): = 111 - _ 2'1 - _“_’1 if - 511 w! 6 W, 911 2 “pal-1% P) (6 2) In general, we expect price elasticities (in absolute value) to be positively correlated with expenditure (income) elasticities. In other words, the demand for a good which is a "luxury" in the sense of being consumed disproportionately by high-income consumers is likely to be more sensitive to changes in price. 1. If Cufo, then the compensated own-price elasticity is wi-l, where w, is the budget share of good i. If 613:0, then the compen- sated cross-price elasticity is wJ. These price elasticities correspond to the most plausible null hypothesis: that budget shares are not affected by prices. In a disaggregated system, the budget shares will be small and these elasticities will be close to -1 and 0, respectively. 166 A comparison of the expenditure elasticities in Table 6-6 and the price elasticities in Table 6-8 confirms this intuition. Factory beer, rice, and white potatoes, all luxuries in the rural sector, have price elasticities (in absolute value) of 2.0 or greater. Other luxuries with price elastic demand include traditional beers, "other meat,” and sugar. Most of the necessities, such as bananas, beans, sorghum, salt, and sweet potatoes, are relatively unresponsive to price. The most counter- intuitive result is the low price elasticity of demand for beef (-0.20). Although only three of the 17 own-price coefficients are signifi- cant at the 95% level, as shown in Table 6-7, the cross-equation joint Table 6-8: Effect of prices on rural food demand — own price own F stat Prob Budget coeff price for all under category “11 t elast prices Ho sofifis 0.23 0.24 -0.83 2.39 0.00 RICE -0.76 -0.76 -2.53 1.34 0.16 CASSA -0.56 -0.42 -1.06 1.41 0.12 SWPOT -1.20 -0.73 -0.97 2.92 0.00 WHPOT -5.75 -2.30 -2.46 5.46 0.00 BANAN 0.92 1.07 -0.85 7.35 . 0.00 BEANS 2.13 0.62 -0.82 4.06 0.00 PEAS -0.69 -0.69 -1.50 1.85 0.02 TOMAT -0.09 -1.19 -1.72 2.32 0.00 BEEF 1.12 1.36 -0.20 1.82 0.02 MEAT -0.46 -0.26 -1.25 1.80 0.02 BBEER -5.84 -2.60 -1.61 1.80 0.02 SBEER -3.96 -l.94 -2.02 4.01 0.00 FBEER -6.19 -2.09 -8.77 2.54 0.00 OIL 0.15 0.26 -0.85 3.32 0.00 SALT 0.38 0.95 -0.62 2.39 0.00 SUGAR -0.13 -0.62 -1.43 2.05 0.01 167 test of all 17 own-price coefficients is significant at the 95% confi- dence level. Furthermore, in 15 of the 17 food equations, the vector of price coefficients is significantly different than zero at the 95% level. Not surprisingly, the cross-equation test of the joint signifi- cance of all 289 price coefficients rejects at the 99$ level the hypothesis that prices have no effect on the budget shares of food (see Appendix B). Derived non-food pficg elasticities: Following Frisch (1959) and Newberry (1987), we derive non-food price elasticities using the assumption of strongly separable preferences, the price and expendi- ture elasticities for food, and the expenditure elasticities for each non-food category. The elasticity of demand for food with respect to household expenditure is 0.85, while the price elasticity of food as a whole is -0.82, and the budget share of food is 0.741. Using equation 4-31, we can calculate the value of o as follows: 4,, fizz+ézwz . -.82 + (.85)(.74) = -0.60 6- efZI-wfet) .ESII-(.7Z)(.ES)I ( 3) By substituting ¢ and the appropriate budget shares and expenditure elasticities into equation 4-30, we can derive the own- and cross-price elasticities of demand for non-food items in the rural area. The uncompensated price elasticities of demand for non-food items in the rural sector are presented in Table 6-9. These should be treated as highly tentative given the particularly strong assumptions required to obtain them. Nonetheless, the high price elasticity of demand for ”luxury" goods such a housing, transportation, and leisure/services is certainly plausible, as is the inelastic demand for tobacco and energy. The expenditure elasticities shown in Table 6-9 have been re- estimated adding food prices to the model but restricting the price 1. Strictly speaking, these figures refer only to the 17 modeled food commodities, thus excluding ”other food" for which no price information is available. The average budget share allocated to "other food” is 9.8%. 168 Table 6-9: Derived rural non-food price elasticities Budget elasticities category share expend price CLOT'IT 6 . 30 1 . 14 -0 FIT HOUSE 3.31 2.78 -1.61 EQUIP 1.54 2.18 -1.30 ENERG 1.19 0.71 -0.44 HEALT 1.68 0.96 -0.59 EDUCA 0.42 1.25 -0.76 TRANS 0.80 2.35 -1.41 TOBAC 0.71 0.79 -0.48 LEISU 0.36 1.97 -1.18 OTHERF 9.87 1.17 -0.74 — coefficients to correspond to the cross-price elasticities derived under additivity assumptionsl. This step causes only slight modification of ‘ E the expenditure elasticities: comparing Tables 6-6 and 6-9, the largest difference in the expenditure elasticities is 0.01. The last line in Table 6-9 shows the price and expenditure elasticities of the omitted category, "other food.” The expenditure and demographic coefficients are defined in such a way to satisfy adding up, while the price coefficients are defined to satisfy homogeneity for the entire system. These results are presented here only because the non- food coefficients must be determined before the coefficients for the excluded "other food" category can be defined. 6.3 $23 mode; of rural demand with symmetry imposed Consistent consumer behavior requires that the matrix of compen- sated substitution effects be symmetric. In Chapter 4, it was shown that, for the demand function used here, symmetric substitution effects imply that the matrix of price coefficients, a”, must be symmetric. 1. This is done by regressing wn-anfpt on the same set of five independent variables plus the constant, where wh is the budget share of non-food category n, 051 is the matrix of food-non-food cross- price coefficients derived using additivity, and p, is the vector of food prices. 169 Since the a matrix is 17x17, imposing symmetry requires 136 restrictions on the estimated coefficientsl. The discussion of the rural model with symmetry will be relatively brief, focusing on the price and expenditure elasticities. The effect of household composition will not be reviewed, and the various joint hypotheses will not be retested. The complete set of coefficients and t statistics from the restricted rural model are presented in Appendix C. Table 6-10 provides the correlation coefficients obtained for the rural demand model with symmetry imposed. Comparing these results with those of the unrestricted rural model (Table_6-4), imposing symmetry appears to reduce the value of R? by 4-6% for most food items. The equations for bananas, beans, and traditional beers suffer the most from the imposition of symmetry. On the other hand, the non-food correlation‘ coefficients remain unchanged in the restricted rural model. The expenditure elasticities from the SUR model with symmetry, presented in Table 6-11, are similar to those without symmetry (see Table 6-6). The expenditure elasticity for sweet potatoes changes from barely positive in the unrestricted model to barely negative in the restricted version. Only one commodity (peas) changes from luxury to necessity, and no commodity switches in the reverse direction. The expenditure elasticities for food commodities are almost all within 0.20 of the unrestricted value, and many are within 0.05. The coefficients‘ and the expenditure elasticities for the non-food categories do not change at all with the symmetry restriction, presumably because these equations do not contain any restricted parameters. By contrast, the estimated food price elasticities in the re- stricted model, presented in Table 6-12, differ considerably from those in the unrestricted model (see Table 6-7). Although factory beer and 1. There are 17:17:289 elements in the matrix, 289-178272 off-diagonal elements, and thus 272/2=136 elements in each off-diagonal triangle. 170 Table 6-10: Summary of rural model with symmetry imposed — Mean Budget budget category share R2 SORGH 1.41 0.11 RICE 0.49 0.06 CASSA 5.92 0.07 SWPOT 12.54 0.32 WHPOT 4.02 0.26 BANAN 5.86 0.06 BEANS 21.61 0.17 PEAS 1.39 0.05 TOMAT 0.13 0.12 BEEF 1.39 0.09 MEAT 1.91 0.10 BBEER 10.15 0.10 SBEER 3.91 0.14 FBEER- 0.80 . 0.19 OIL 0.96 0.17 SALT 1.02 0.17 SUGAR 0.31 0.07 CLOTH 6.30 0.06 HOUSE 3.31 0.18 EQUIP 1.54 0.04 ENERG 1.19 0.03 HEALT 1.68 0.01 EDUCA 0.42 0.03 TRANS 0.80 0.07 TOBAC 0.71 0.01 LEISU 0.36 0.01 white potatoes are the most price-elastic food commodities in both versions, rice and oil become highly inelastic in the restricted version, while beans and sugar become considerably more price elastic. Although such a judgement is necessarily subjective, the price elastici- ties estimated with symmetry restrictions seem, on the whole, less credible than do the unrestricted price elasticities. This is most notable in the cases of oil, rice, and beans. Under symmetry, the expenditure elasticity of food (0.86) is almost the same as in the unrestricted version (0.85). The price elasticity of food (-0.90) is more elastic than the corresponding figure from the unrestricted model (-0.82). Substituting these values into equation 6-3, the value of O for the rural model under symmetry is 171 Table 6-11: Effect of expenditure on rural demand under symmetry ln(exp) Budget ln(exp) sqrd expend category 31 t B; t elast SORGH -17.48 -1.91 0.84 1.83 0.30 RICE 3.29 0.51 -0.15 -0.46 1.71 CASSA 20.83 0.66 -1.21 -0.76 0.54 SWPOT -105.13 -2.88 4.69 2.54 -0.08 WHPOT 67.42 2.35 -3.30 -2.27 1.72 BANAN 9.05 0.31 -0.38 -0.25 1.28 BEANS 85.34 1.81 -4.68 -l.96 0.72 PEAS 8.24 0.62 --0.44 -0.65 0.77 TOMAT 0.53 0.28 -0.03 -0.30 0.86 BEEF -1.22 -0.13 0.12 0.25 1.77 MEAT 2.24 0.12 -0.04 - -0.04 1.75 BBEER 3.41 0.09 0.01 0.01 1.36 SBEER 24.31 1.11 -1.22 -1.10 1.13 FBEER -16.03 -1.47 0.89 1.62 2.78 OIL 9.37 1.40 . -0.45 -1.33 1.62 SALT 3.16 0.88 -0.18 -1.01 0.59 SUGAR 1.68 0.34 -0.07 -0.27 2.22 CLOTH 2.63 0.12 -0.09 -0.08 1.15 HOUSE -92.54 -2.95 5.04 3.17 2.77 EQUIP 6.74 0.39 -0.25 -0.29 2.17 ENERG 1.69 0.18 -0.10 -0.21 0.72 HEALT 3.30 0.37 -0.17 -0.38 0.96 EDUCA 4.30 0.62 -0.21 -0.61 1.25 TRANS -5.33 -0.64 0.33 0.78 2.35 TOBAC -0.41 -0.08 0.01 0.05 0.80 LEISU 3.34 0.47 -0.15 -0.42 1.97 -0.83. Under the assumption of additive preferences, this parameter is used to derive the non-food price elasticities shown in Table 6-13. A comparison of the rural non-food elasticities in the unrestrict- ed and restricted versions of the model reveals that the restricted non- food price elasticities follow roughly the same rank order as the unrestricted elasticities.i In both versions, the most price elastic categories are housing, transportation, and household equipment, while the least price responsive are tobacco and energy. On the other hand, the restricted figures are consistently more price elastic. This pattern reflects the fact that imposing symmetry increases the price elasticity of food without changing appreciably the expenditure elasticity of food. Under the assumption of additive “new '5 3: ‘. (Fun-2v Table 6-12: 172 Effect of prices on rural food demand under symmetry own price own Budget coeff price category “11 t elast SORGH 0.08 0109 -0.93 RICE 0.46 0.50 -0.08 CASSA -2.08 -1.80 -1.32 SWPOT -1.22 -0.80 -0.96 WHPOT -6.10 —3.25 -2.55 BANAN 2.63 3.80 -0.57 BEANS -3.78 -1.14 -1.11 PEAS -2.00 -2.53 -2.43 TOMAT —0.04 -0.62 -1.34 BEEF 0.31 0.41 -0.79 MEAT -1.00 -0.64 -1.54 BBEER -1.66 -0.82 -1.20 SBEER -1.87 -1.04 -1.48 FBEER -6.46 -2.36 -9.12 OIL 0.70 1.37 -0.28 SALT 0.42 1.14 -0.58 SUGAR -0.41 -2.17 -2.32 “I?!” Table 6-13: Derived rural non-food price elasticities under symmetry Budget elasticities category share expend price CLOTH 6.30 1.15 -0.96 HOUSE 3.31 2.79 -2.19 EQUIP 1.54 2.18 -1.78 ENERG 1.19 0.72 -0.61 HEALT 1.68 0.96 -0.81 EDUCA 0.42 1.25 -1.04 TRANS 0.80 2.36 -1.94 TOBAC 0.71 0.79 -0.66 LEISU 0.36 1.97 -l.63 OTHFO 9.87 1.06 -0.90 preferences, the relationship between price and expenditure elasticities is assumed constant across strongly separable categories. 173 6.4 Un st cte UR model of urban demand This section reviews the results of the model of urban demand without symmetry. As noted in section 6.1.2, the urban food classifica- tion is similar to the rural classification except that the former includes bread, milk, and prepared meals, and it disaggregates cassava into cassava root and cassava flour. In addition, the urban model includes the category ”vegetables," where the rural model has only "tomatoes." Thus, the urban model includes 21 food equations and 9 non- food equations. With six coefficients common to all 30 equations and 21 price terms in each of the 21 food equations, the unrestricted urban model involves the simultaneous estimation of 621 coefficients. As in the case of the rural model, only selected results are presented here. The full set of coefficients and t statistics is given in Appendix C. 6.4.1 ngpgll ggogpess-gf-fft apd gfgpfffggpgp In general, the urban model provides a better fit to the data than does the rural model. As shown in Table 6-14, three commodity equations in the urban model (beans, sweet potatoes, and white potatoes) have correlation coefficients (R2) above 0.35, but only one equation in the rural model (sweet potatoes) reaches this level. Similarly, five of the nine non-food categories have R2 values above 0.10 in the urban model, whereas only one does in the rural model. Another indication of the better fit of the urban model is the fact that the independent variables are jointly significant in almost every equation. Table 6-14 shows that for 27 out of 30 commodity equations, we can reject the hypothesis that all the coefficients are zero at the 99% confidence level. The null hypothesis can be rejected at the 95% confidence level for two more goods. Only in the case of clothing are the coefficients jointly insignificant. The higher level of explanatory power of the urban demand model is probably due to the greater variability in income and household expendi- I'_‘. .‘I . 174 Table 6-14: Summary of unrestricted SUR model of urban demand — Mean F stat Prob Budget budget for all under category share R2 variab Ho SORGH 0.92 0.14 1.57 0.03 RICE 2.37 0.15 2.06 0.00 BREAD 0.67 0.21 2.78 0.00 'CASSA 1.79 0.31 5.06 0.00 SWPOT 3.84 0.49 10.37 0.00 WHPOT 6.24 0.38 6.50 0.00 BANAN 2.93 0.18 2.56 0.00 CASFL 2.40 0.26 3.73 0.00 BEANS 10.37 0.51 11.01 0.00 PEAS 0.41 0.20 2.62 ' 0.00 VEGET 1.57 0.17 2.27 0.00- BEEF 2.90 0.21 2.93 0.00 MEAT 2.11 0.13 1.69 _0.02 MILK 2.30’ 0.19 2.76 0.00 BBEER 4.82 0.35 5.74 0.00 SBEER 1.16 0.23 3.08 0.00 FBEER 4.17 0.23 3.43 0.00 OIL 2.07 0.19 2.65 0.00 SALT 0.54 0.32 4.99 0.00 SUGAR 2.59 0.26 4.26 0.00 MEALS 2.76 0.19 2.77 0.00 CLOTH 5.50 0.02 1.18 0.24 HOUSE 10.04 0.34 27.86 0.00 EQUIP 2.87 0.16 10.80 0.00 ENERG 4.62 0.11 6.50 0.00 HEALT 3.05 0.07 4.36 0.00 EDUCA 1.07 0.06 3.57 0.00 TRANS 4.84 0.18 12.32 0.00 TOBAC 1.51 0.09 5.50 0.00 LEISU 1.88 0.29 23.01 0.00 ture (see section 5.3.2). In addition, the ”lumpiness” of non-food spending is less of a problem in the urban areas because household expenditure is generally greater and the percentage allocated to non- food categories is higher. A S 20 radio represents ”only" one half the annual expenditure on leisure/services of an average urban household, compared to 10 times the leisure/services spending of a typical rural household. 7 6.4.2 Effect of total expenditure The expenditure elasticities for the unrestricted model of urban food demand are shown in Table 6-15. Comparing the urban and 175 rural expenditure elasticities, it is interesting that the rank order of the products is quite similar, but that the elasticities are generally lower in the urban sector. Table 6-15: Effect of household expenditure on urban demand — ln(exp) F stat Prob Budget ln(exp) sqrd expend for under category 81 t 8? t elast expend Ho 30368 -1.95 -0.71 0.07 0.58 0.59 2.85 0.06 RICE 17.19 3.96 -0.81 -3.95 1.10 7.83 0.00 BREAD 5.27 3.36 -0.24 -3.22 1.42 8.57 0.00 CASSA 3.27 0.76 -0.21 -1.05 0.34 . 13.10 0.00 SWPOT ~28.57 -3.75 1.20 3.35 0.12 31.59 0.00 WHPOT 10.28 1.45 -0.56 -1.69 0.75 10.18 0.00 BANAN -1.47 -0.25 -0.00 -0.01 0.47 10.82 0.00 CASFL -4.20. -0.86 0.13 0.57 0.40 13.09 0.00 BEANS -23.30 -1.84 0.77 1.29 0.31 48.48 0.00 PEAS 0.43 0.24 -0.02 -0.28 0.86 0.24 0.79 VEGET 3.98 1.98 -0.19 -2.02 0.98 2.27 0.10 BEEF 18.83 4.15 -0.90 -4.22 0.96 9.57 0.00 MEAT 5.53 1.29 -0.26 -1.26 1.08 0.91 0.40 MILK 10.18 1.82 -0.49 -1.86 0.97 1.89 0.15 BBEER 19.19 1.93 -0.98 -2.11 0.69 6.68 0.00 SBEER -0.10 -0.03 -0.01 -0.07 0.68 1.47 0.23 FBEER 13.07 1.30 -0.50 -1.06 1.60 9.25 0.00 OIL 10.29 4.05 -0.49 -4.08 1.02 8.43 0.00 SALT -0.36 -0.49 0.00 0.15 0.53 18.75 0.00 SUGAR 11.59 2.91 -0.55 -2.94 1.00 4.48 0.01 MEALS -19.41 -1.43 0.90 1.41 0.82 1.07 0.34 CLOTH 9.81 1.35 -0.46 -1.33 1.04 0.94 0.39 HOUSE -63.88 -3.26 3.49 3.77 1.94 53.91 0.00 EQUIP 1.41 0.24 0.03 0.11 1.72 22.31 0.00 ENERG 22.05 2.98 -0.98 -2.80 1.33 10.19 0.00 HEALT 7.42 1.71 --0.34 -1.65 1.10 1.97 0.14 EDUCA 5.25 1.00 -0.23 -0.93 1.36 1.25 0.29 TRANS -14.90 -1.25 0.88 _1.56 1.72 18.25 0.00 TOBAC 7.59 2.13 -0.38 -2.28 0.68 6.73 0.00 LEISU -4.25 -1.04 0.26 1.35 1.66 18.67 0.00 For example, among food categories, in both urban and rural areas the highest expenditure elasticities are those of factory beer, sugar, rice, oil, and animal products, while the lowest are those of cassava root, sweet potatoes, beans, bananas, and salt. Bread, a category not included in the rural model, is a "luxury" good, with an expenditure 176 elasticity second only to factory beer among food commodities. This is not surprising given the fact that, on a per calorie basis, bread is three times as expensive as sweet potatoes in the urban sector. Among the non-food categories, the highest expenditure elastici- ties in both rural and urban areas are those of housing, household equipment, and transportation. In both cases, tobacco has one of the lowest expenditure elasticities of the non-food categories. One important difference is that energy is a luxury among urban households but a necessity among rural households (although the latter elasticity is not significantly below 1.0). . As mentioned above, the urban expenditure elasticities are generally lower than in the rural elasticities. For example, none of the urban budget categories has an elasticities over 2.0, while there are five such categories in the rural model. One implication is that some of the goods that are ”luxuries" in the countryside, such as white potatoes and traditional beers, are "necessities" in the cities. In the urban model, the expenditure elasticities of food and non- food are 0.72 and 1.52, respectively. By contrast, the corresponding expenditure elasticities in the rural model are 0.85 and 1.591. It may seem paradoxical that both food and non-food categories have lower expenditure elasticities in the urban model, since the weighted average of all expenditure elasticities must be 1.0 in any system, according to the Engel aggregation condition. The explanation is that the non-food elasticities, which are higher on average, are weighted more heavily in the urban model because non-food categories represent a much larger share of the urban budgets. According to the F test in Table 6-15, the two expenditure terms are jointly significant at the 99% level in 20 of the 30 equations (for 1. .The average food elasticities cited here exclude the category "other food,“ whose expenditure elasticity is derived as a residual. Thus, the weighted average of the two elasticities presented here is not exactly equal to 1.0. r ’.'-'. 11.314 .nl‘. x I 177 the other ten, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that budget share is constant across expenditure levels). Given this result, it is not surprising that the 60 expenditure terms in the complete model are jointly significant at the 99% confidence level (F a 10.47). Finally, Table 6-15 indicates that there is significant curvature in the relationship between budget share and log expenditure. The quadratic expenditure coefficient (82) is significant in eleven of the 30 equations, as indicated by the t statistic. Furthermore, this coefficient is jointly significant in the system at the 99% confidence level (F = 2.94). 6.4.3 'Effect of household composition Of the 90 coefficients representing the effect of house- hold composition on urban food budget shares, about one third (31) are significantly different than zero at the 95% confidence level, as shown in Table 6-16. The two household size variables are jointly significant for the unrestricted urban model as a whole (F s 5.06), as is the sex of the head of household (F a 3.32). The coefficients for number of adults and number of children (71 and 72) indicate the effect of an additional family member given the same prices and real expenditure per adult-equivalent. These results show that, at the 95% confidence level, a larger family allocates a greater share of its budget to bread, cassava flour, "other meat,” milk, oil, sugar, and most of the non-food categories, while devoting a smaller share to cassava root, beans, traditional beers, meals away from home, and tobacco. The first group has expenditure elasticities close to or above 1.0, while every good in the second group has an elasticity below 1.0. Thus, an increase in household size while holding expendi- ture per adult equivalent constant has an effect on budget allocations similar to an increase in total expenditure. These results correspond to the hypothesis of economies of scale in household size, as discussed in section 6.2.3. 178 Table 6-16: Effect of household composition on urban demand IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-I-I-I-III-I-l-IIII-I number number sex of Budget adults childr head category 71 t 12 t 73' t SORGH -0.10 -1.26 -0.03 -0.78 -0.06 -0.23 RICE -0.13 -1.06 0.12 1.73 -0.06 -0.14 BREAD 0.09 1.95 0.06 2.55 0.07 0.48 CASSA -0.32 -2.54 0.12 1.82 -0.72 -1.76 SWPOT —0.37 -1.70 -0.14 -1.18 0.39 0.54 WHPOT -0.19 -0.95 0.07 0.66 0.36 0.53 BANAN -0.05 —0.32 0.04 0.39 1.03 1.83 CASFL 0.00 0.00 0.17 2.22 0.50 1.07 BEANS -1.26 -3.49 -0.45 -2.29 -0.75 -0.62 PEAS -0.00 -0.03 0.01 0.20 -0.17 -1.02 VEGET 0.13 2.29 0.01 0.32 0.53 2.80 BEEF -0.12 -0.90 0.10 1.40 -0.45 -1.05 MEAT 0.29 2.35 0.09 1.33 0.03 0.07 MILK 0.33 2.06 0.09 1.08 0.76 1.43 BBEER -1.19 -4.17 -0.63 -4.12 -4.46 -4.74‘ SBEER -0.15 -1.33 -0.13 -2.19 -0.63 -1.71 FBEER -0.30 -1.05 -0.08 -0.52 -2.08 -2.18 OIL -0.00 -0.02 0.11 2.74 0.50 2.08 SALT -0.01 -0.34 -0.02 -1.36 0.12 1.76 SUGAR -0.01 -0.12 0.14 2.25 1.33 3.51 MEALS -1.15 -2.93 -0.82 -3.93 -2.89 -2.25 CLOTH 0.22 1.13 0.09 0.83 -0.36 -0.53 HOUSE 1.26 2.42 0.22 0.73 1.67 0.91 EQUIP 0.21 1.32 0.17 1.87 0.37 0.67 ENERG 0.44 2.25 0.22 1.98 0.92 1.33 HEALT 0.38 3.29 0.11 1.63 0.69 1.69 EDUCA 0.12 0.85 0.26 3.20 1.32 2.68 TRANS 1.22 3.86 0.35 1.91 1.39 1.25 TOBAC -0.16 -1.71 -0.19 -3.46 —1.03 -3.09 LEISU 0.79 7.28 0.04 0.69 0.40 1.04 Turning our attention to the effect of the gender of the head of household, Table 6-16 reveals that, other things equal, female-headed households allocate a smaller portion of their budget to banana beer, factory beer, meals away from home, and tobacco, while spending a larger share on vegetables, cooking oil, sugar, and education. In the case of banana beer and prepared meals, the coefficients (Ya) are close in magnitude to the corresponding mean budget shares, implying that spending on these items by female-headed household is virtually non- existent. 179 The smaller shares allocated to banana beer, factory beer, and tobacco clearly reflect social norms. Similarly, eating at restaurants and bars is less acceptable for women in Rwanda. The lower spending on sugar and cooking oil by male-headed household may be simply the result of under-reporting in these households: women generally do the shopping but the interviews were more often carried out with the (male) heads of household. 6.4-4 W As in the rural model, the effect of food prices on the demand for food is estimated directly as part of.the SUR model. Non- food price effects are not estimated but derived under the assumptions of strongly separable preferences. The results of each procedure are discussed in turn. Estimated food price elasticities: The uncompensated own-price elasticities in the urban areas, shown in Table 6-17, are similar to those in the rural areas, although there are a few unexpected differences. As in the rural model, rice and traditional beer are relatively price elastic, while salt, cassava root, and beans are price inelastic. In fact, the estimated own-price elasticities of salt and cassava root are positive, although they are not significantly greater than zerol. Somewhat surprising are the low price elasticities of bread and factory beer. Since neither elasticities is significantly less than one, this may be simply the result of insufficient variability in price within the urban areas. Also unexpected were the relatively high price elasticities of sweet potatoes, cassava flour, and sorghum. One possible explanation is that the greater degree of choice among staples in the cities makes demand more sensitive to price. 1. The t statistic associated with a“ tests the null hypoth- esis that the budget share does not vary with own-price. For goods with a small budget share, like cassava root and salt, this essentially corresponds to a test of the null hypothesis that the uncompensated own- price elasticity is -1 (see footnote in section 6.2.4). 180 The t test on the own-price coefficients in the urban model, presented in the second and third columns of Table 6-17, reveal that six of the 21 goods have own-price terms which are significant at the 95% confidence level. The F test of the joint effect of all 21 own-price terms indicates that they are statistically significant at the 99% confidence level (F = 5.23). The F tests shown in the last two columns of Table 6-17 indicate F” that the price vector is significantly different than zero at the 95% confidence level in 13 of the 21 equations. Looking at the model as a Table 6-17: Effect of prices on urban food demand IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-II own price own F stat Prob Budget coeff price for all under category a“ t elast prices Ho SORGH -0.48 -1.37 -1.52 0.93 0.55 RICE -3.77 -3.00 -2.59 1.53 0.06 BREAD 0.23 1.47 -0.65 1.47 0.07 CASSA 2.01 4.15 0.13 3.96 0.00 SWPOT -1.88 -2.11 -1.46 4.36 0.00 WHPOT -1.61 -0.90 -l.24 4.75 0.00 BANAN -0.90 —1.89 -1.29 1.31 0.15 CASFL -1.19 -l.95 -1.48 1.67 0.03 BEANS 2.98 1.26 -0.64 2.43 0.00 PEAS -0.16 -0.69 -1.38 3.02 0.00 VEGET -0.21 -0.84 -1.13 1.61 0.04 BEEF -0.25 -0.51 -1.08 1.91 0.01 MEAT -0.34 -0.74 -1.16 1.45 0.09 MILK 0.71 1.20 -0.69 2.31 0.00 BBEER -6.30 -6.03 -2.29 3.08 0.00 SBEER -0.98 -2.08 -1.84 2.56 0.00 FBEER 0.74 0.41 -0.85 1.37 0.12 OIL 0.21 1.13 -0.90 1.22 0.22 SALT 0.60 4.26 0.12 1.42 0.10 SUGAR 0.19 0.62 -0.93 3.04 0.00 MEALS -0.99 -1.17 -1.35 1.77 0.02 181 whole, the price terms are jointly significant at the 99% confidence level. Derived non-food price elasticities: The non-food price elasticities for the urban sector are derived under the assumption of strongly separable preferences. Substituting into equation 6-3 the average urban food share (0.59), the expenditure elasticity of food (0.72), and the price elasticity of food (-0.91), the value of 6 is F?“ calculated as -1.17. Combining this parameter with the non-food ‘ expenditure elasticities, the non-food price elasticities are calculated as shown in Table 6-18. Table 6-18: Derived effect of prices on urban non-food demand _. Budget elasticities category share expend price CLOTH 5.50 1.04 -1.20 HOUSE 10.04 1.93 -2.02 EQUIP 2.87 1.72 -1.97 ENERG 4.62 1.33 -1.52 HEALT 3.05 1.10 -1.28 EDUCA 1.07 1.36 -1.59 TRANS 4.84 1.72 -1.93 TOBAC 1.51 0.69 -O.80 LEISU 1.88 1.66 -1.92 OTHERF 5.69 0.69 -O.80 As in the rural model, these elasticities must be considered highly tentative. Housing, household equipment, transportation, and leisure/services are price elastic, while tobacco is the only price inelastic non-food category, according to these calculations. As explained in section 6.2.4, the expenditure elasticities in this table reflect minor changes due to the re-estimation of the non- food categories imposing the price terms derived under additive prefer- ences. Only in the case of tobacco is the adjustment noticeable at the level of precision presented in Table 6-18. 182 Finally, having completed the estimation of the 26 food and non- food categories, we derive the coefficients for the excluded budget category, "other food." The expenditure and household composition coefficients are defined so as to satisfy adding up, while the price terms are defined to satisfy homogeneity in the complete system. It is difficult to evaluate the plausibility of the estimates for ”other food," but it is worth noting that the price and expenditure elastici- ties (-0.80 and 0.69) are similar to the averages for the explicitly modeled food categories (-0.91 and 0.72). 6.5 SUR model of urban demgnd with symmetry impoggg In this section, we briefly consider the results of the urban model when symmetry of compensated cross-price substitution effects is imposed. Since the estimated price terms form a 21x21 matrix, symmetry requires imposing 210 restrictions on the urban SUR model. The correlation coefficients (R2) for the urban equations are presented in Table 6-19. The non-food equations are unaffected by the restrictions placed on the food price terms. With regard to the food equations, except in a few cases (beans, sweet potatoes, and white potatoes), the reduction in the value of R2 is generally around 3-5 percentage points. A Wald test of the 210 restrictions rejects the null hypothesis of symmetry at the 99% confidence level. However, we retain the symmetric demand model as one alternative because the willingness- to-pay calculations used in Chapter 7 require symmetry to qualify as well-defined measures of welfare. The expenditure elasticities in the urban model with symmetry imposed are presented in Table 6-20. Under symmetry, the expenditure elasticities of sweet potatoes, beans, and prepared meals fall, with sweet potatoes becoming slightly inferior. On the whole, however, the expenditure elasticities are not greatly affected by the symmetry restriction. Table 6-19: Summary of urban model with symmetry imposed IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-II Mean Budget budget category share R2 SORGH 0.92 0.11 RICE 2.37 0.12 BREAD 0.67 0.19 CASSA 1.79 0.27 SWPOT 3.84 0.39 WHPOT 6.24 0.29 BANAN 2.93 0.14 CASFL 2.40 0.22 BEANS 10.37 0.45 PEAS 0.41 0.15 VEGET 1.57 0.16 BEEF 2.90 0.17 MEAT 2.11 0.07 MILK 2.30 0.13 BBEER 4.82 0.28 SBEER 1.16 0.14 FBEER 4.17 0.18 OIL 2.07 0.16 SALT 0.54 0.31 SUGAR 2.59 0.22 MEALS 2.76 0.12 CLOTH 5.50 0.02 HOUSE 10.04 0.34 EQUIP 2.87 0.16 ENERG 4.62 0.11 HEALT 3.05 0.07 EDUCA 1.07 0.06 TRANS 4.84 0.18 TOBAC 1.51 0.09 LEISU 1.88 0.29 183 The estimated price elasticities, on the other hand, are substan- tially affected by imposing symmetry, as shown in Table 6-21. The price elasticities of sweet potatoes and salt, which were slightly positive in the unrestricted model, become slightly negative in the model with symmetry. Six other food price elasticities change by at least 0.20: rice and factory beer become more price responsive under symmetry, while sorghum, white potatoes, milk, and sorghum beer become less so. Symmetry does not affect the urban expenditure elasticity for food as a whole (0.72), but it does increase the price elasticity of food somewhat (from -0.87 to -0.91). Because of the fixed relationship 184 Table 6-20: Effect of expenditure on urban demand under symmetry ln(exp) Budget ln(exp) sqrd expend category 32 t 82 t elast SORGH -1.59 -0.59 0.06 0.44 0.56 RICE 18.87 4.39 -0.88 -4.34 1.18 BREAD 5.24 3.37 -0.24 -3.23 1.41 CASSA 4.49 1.06 -0.26 -1.33 0.40 SWPOT -35.19 -4.72 1.48 4.22 -0.06 WHPOT 8.50 1.22 -0.49 -1.50 0.70 BANAN -1.06 -0.19 -0.02 -0.07 0.51 CASFL -5.32 -1.11 0.18 0.81 0.39 BEANS -25.85 -2.09 0.86 1.47 0.24 PEAS 0.02 0.01 -0.01 -0.07 0.75 VEGET ,4.29 2.16 -0.20 - -2.19 0.99 BEEF 22.18 4.99 -1.05 -5.02 1.03 MEAT 5.36 1.27 -0.24 -1.23 1.11 MILK 9.42 1.72 -0.45 -1.75 0.97 BBEER 22.52 2.34 _ -1.14 -2.51 0.69 SBEER -0.98 -O.26 0.02 0.13 0.57 FBEER 12.18 1.24 -0.45 -0.98 1.64 OIL 11.15 4.46 -0.53 -4.47 1.05 SALT -0.45 -0.62 0.01 0.26 0.50 SUGAR 11.41 2.92 -0.54 -2.94 1.01 MEALS -17.51 -1.34 0.84 1.36 1.04 CLOTH 9.81 1.35 -0.46 -1.33 1.04 HOUSE -63.88 -3.26 3.49 3.77 1.94 EQUIP 1.41 0.24 0.03 0.11 1.72 ENERG 22.05 2.98 -0.98 -2.80 1.33 HEALT 7.42 1.71 -0.34 -1.65 1.10 EDUCA 5.25 1.00 -0.23 -0.93 1.36 TRANS -14.90 -1.25 0.88 1.56 1.72 TOBAC 7.59 2.13 -0.38 -2.28 0.68 LEISU -4.25 -1.04 0.26 1.35 1.66 between price and expenditure elasticities of strongly separable commodity groups, this result make the non-food price elasticities somewhat greater under symmetry than in the unrestricted model. As shown in Table 6-22, the derived non-food price elasticities for the urban model with symmetry are roughly 0.10 greater than those without the symmetry restrictions. The relatively high price elasticity of demand for housing, household equipment, and transportation and the relatively inelastic demand for tobacco remain unchanged, however. The coefficients of "other food," defined to satisfy adding up and homogeneity, generate elasticities which are roughly the same as those 185 Table 6-21: Effect of prices on urban food demand with symmetry imposed — own price own Budget coeff price category “11 t elast SORGH -0.28 -0.88 -1.30 RICE -3.04 -2.91 -2.29 BREAD 0.15 1.03 -0.77 CASSA 1.50 3.33 -0.15 SWPOT -2.60 -3.17 -1.64 WHPOT -0.16 -0.11 -1.01 BANAN -0.85 -1.91 -1.27 CASFL -0.96 —1.72 -1.38 BEANS 1.59 0.79 -0.77 PEAS -0.13 -0.62 -1.31 VEGET -0.12 -0.59 -1.08 BEEF -0.07 -0.18 -1.03 MEAT -0.43 -1.05 -1.20 MILK 1.25 2.32 -0.46~ BBEER -5.51 -5.72 -2.13 . SBEER -O.39 -O.93 -1.33 . FBEER -0.54 -0.34 -1.16 L OIL 0.04 0.26 -0.98 SALT 0.49 3.86 -0.09 SUGAR 0.04 0.14 -0.99 MEALS -1.25 -1.57 -1.45 obtained in the unrestricted model. 6.6 Effgct of zero expenditures on model This section presents a brief digression to compare the rural food results obtained from the linear model with those of the Tobit model which adjusts for the fact that the dependent variable (budget share) is limited to being non-negative. We do not adopt the Tobit model for subsequent analysis because of the problems discussed in section 3.3.3, primarily the difficulty in imposing adding up and symmetry on the system.‘ The test is limited to comparing OLS estimation of rural food demand estimation and Tobit estimation of rural food demand (single- equation OLS results are used for compariSon because the Tobit model is also estimated equation-by-equation). 186 Table 6-22: Derived non-food price elasticities under symmetry Budget elasticities category share expend price croia 5.50 1.04 -1.11 HOUSE 10.04 1.93 -1.88 EQUIP 2.87 1.72 -1.82 ENERG 4.62 1.33 -1.41 HEALT 3.05 1.10 -1.18 EDUCA 1.07 1.36 -1.47 TRANS 4.84 1.72 -1.79 TOBAC 1.51 0.69 -0.74 LEISU 1.88 1.66 -1.77 OTHFO 5.69 0.74 -0.81 The software package LIMDEP is used to implement the Tobit estimation of rural food demand. The marginal effect of each indepen-4 dent variable on the dependent variable is calculated using the expres- sion given in MacDonald and Moffitt (1980). These partial derivatives are then used to evaluate the price and income elasticities at the means. Table 6-23 compares elasticities obtained with the Tobit model to those obtained from the unrestricted linear model. Several patterns can be identified from this table. First, as expected, for goods consumed by a high proportion of the households, the differences between the two models is negligible. This is the case for the basic staple commodities such as sweet potatoes, cassava, bananas, and beans, as well as banana beer and salt. Overall, eight of the 17 expenditure elasticities differ by less than 0.10, while nine of the 17 price elasticities differ by less than 0.20. The divergence between the two models is greatest for the goods consumed by less than a quarter of the sample: tomatoes, rice, and sugar. Only one good (tomatoes) is a luxury in one model and a necessi- ty in the other (none change in the other direction). And just one commodity (sugar) is price inelastic in one model and price elastic in the other (none switch from elastic to inelastic). 187 Table 6-23: Comparison of elasticities estimated with Tobit and OLS — Mean % hhs expenditure price budget consum- elasticities elasticities Product share ing Tobit OLS Tobit OLS SORGH 1.41 58.9 0.70 0.48 -0.90 -0.77 RICE 0.49 23.7 2.11 1.83 -1.86 -3.15 CASSA 5.92 79.6 0.58 0.45 -1.09 -1.05 SWPOT 12.54 96.7 0.04 -0.00 -0.96 -0.96 WHPOT 4.02 64.4 1.78 1.82 -1.86 -2.41 BANAN 5.86 80.7 1.09 1.02 -0.80 -0.81 BEANS 21.86 100.0 0.62 0.62 -0.89 -0.89 PEAS 1.39 44.8 1.37 1.07 -1.03 -1.84 TOMAT 0.13 21.9 1.63 0.68 -1.17 -1.77 BEEF 1.39 63.0 1.82 1.66 -0.61 -0.18 OTHMT 1.91 44.4 2.06 1.79 -1.52 -1.37 BBEER 10.15 90.4 1.42 1.36 -1.59 -1.65 SBEER 3.91 72.2 1.19 1.23 -1.68 -1.97 FBEER 0.80 26.7 2.74 2.87 -1.11 -8.49 OIL 0.96 45.9 1.82 1.58 -0.96 -0.94 SALT 1.02 87.0 0.56 0.55 -0.62 -0.55 SUGAR 0.31 21.5 2.22 2.28 -0.86 -1.25 Second, the divergence between the two models is greater for the price elasticities than for the expenditure elasticities. For example, among expenditure elasticities, the gap between the two estimates is greater than 0.35 for only one good (tomatoes). By contrast, among price elasticities, the divergence is larger than this for seven commodities (factory beer, rice, peas, tomatoes, white potatoes, beef, and sugar). Third, the price elasticities tend to be closer to -1.0 in the Tobit model. In the case of goods with price inelastic demand, this is may be the result of the bias in the Tobit model identified by Pitt (1983). He notes that, by forcing the same parameters to predict both the probability of positive budget shares and the expected budget share among consumers, the Tobit estimates are biased when the signs of these effects are different. This occurs with price insensitive goods since an increase in price lowers the probability of consumption but raises the expected budget share among those who consume it. In this case, the 188 price parameter, «1;: is biased toward zero and the price elasticity is biased toward -1. This bias may explain the fact that the Tobit price elasticities for the three most price-insensitive goods (sorghum, salt, and beef) are considerably closer to -1.0 than the corresponding OLS estimates. In summary, the differences between the elasticity estimates of the Tobit model and the OLS model are relatively small, particularly for staple commodities and other goods consumed by a majority of the households. In the case of price insensitive goods, the differences between the two models may be due to biases in the Tobit model. For the purposes of this analysis, the arguable statistical advantages of the Tobit model do not seem to outweigh the problem that restrictions from economic theory (adding up and symmetry) cannot be imposed. As dis- cussed in Chapter 3, symmetry is necessary for the "willingness-to-pay" measures to be well-defined. 6-7 W In this section, we briefly explore the possibility that the estimated price elasticities are affected by quality effects and/or measurement error. Following Deaton (1987 and 1988), it is assumed that there is no true price variation within the sample cluster. This assumption means that quality and measurement error effects can be tested in two ways which are explained in turn. In order to simplify the analysis, the results are based on single—equation OLS regression. 6.7.1 Effgct of household expenditure on prices paid Any significant (positive) effect of household expendi- ture on the average "price" (unit value) paid for a good within the cluster must be the result of quality effects since true prices are presumed constant in each cluster. Thus, the elasticity of unit value with respect to household expenditure within the cluster may be inter- 1r 189 preted as the "elasticity of quality with respect to household expendi- ture.” This relationship is tested by regressing ”unit values" on total expenditure and household composition, using only within-cluster variation in each variable (this is equivalent to adding a dummy variable for each cluster in the sample). The first column of Table 6- 24 shows the estimated quality elasticities for the rural sector, while the second and third columns give the F statistic for the joint impact of the two expenditure terms and the corresponding probability under the null hypothesis. The rural quality elasticities are relatively low: 13 of the 17 are 0.05 or less and six are even negative. The highest values are for E tomatoes (0.14), bananas (0.09), and banana beer (0.08). Furthermore, in none of the equations can we reject the null hypothesis that there are no expenditure effects, even at the 90% confidence level. Thus, there is little or no evidence of quality effects in rural food demand. Table 6-25 presents the results for the urban food demand model. Here, the estimated quality elasticities are even lower: all but one is below 0.05 and nine of the 21 are negative. And again, in none of the equations are the expenditure terms statistically significant, even at the 90% confidence levell. Thus, urban food demand also reveals little or no sign of quality effects. 6.7.2 Effect of within-cluster unit value on budget share Assuming that prices do not vary within the cluster, a significant effect of "price" (unit value) on demand within the cluster is probably due to measurement error. Measurement error can generate this pattern since, for a given monetary value of a transaction, a 1. The largest quality elasticity is for prepared meals, 0.23. This product also comes closest to being statistically signifi- cant at the 90% confidence level. 190 Table 6-24: Quality and measurement error effects in rural food demand — Estimation of budget share2 Estimation of unit values1 Impact of Impact of expenditure unit values Prod elast F prob F prob SORGH -0.03 0.55 0.84 1.30 0.27 RICE 0.03 8.72 0.11 0.90 0.65 CASSA 0.04 0.61 0.80 1.24 0.32 ii SWPOT 0.03 0.64 0.79 0.42 1.00 WHPOT 0.05 1.71 0.44 0.73 0.85 BANAN 0.09 0.60 0.81 0.52 0.98 BEANS -0.06 1.65 0.45 0.67 0.90 PEAS -0.01 0.24 0.98 0.95 0.59 TOMAT 0.14 1.87 0.41 0.88 0.68 BEEF 0.01 0.05 1.00 0.96 0.58 MEAT 0.02 0.38 0.92 0.56 0.97 BBEER 0.08 2.61 0.32 1.70 0.10 SBEER 0.05 1.67 0.45 0.50 0.99 FBEER -0.01 0.58 0.82 1.02 0.51 E: OIL 0.07 2.35 0.35 0.89 0.66 SALT -0.02 1.13 0.58 1.24 0.32 SUGAR -0.00 0.21 0.99 2.37 0.02 1. Price (unit value) is regressed on log expenditure, log expenditure squared, number of adults, number of children, a dummy for female-headed household and dummy variables for each sample cluster. 2. Budget share is regressed on log expenditure, log expenditure squared, number of adults, number of children, a dummy for female- headed households, prices (unit values), and dummy variables for each sample cluster. positive error in quantity generates a negative error in ”pricel." The test is implemented by estimating the standard demand equa- tion, but using the deviations from the cluster mean as observations (this is equivalent to including dummy variables for each sample cluster). If the price vector is statistically significant within clusters, then measurement error is a likely cause. 1. This relationship could also result from quality effects if richer households spend the same portion of their budget on a good as do poorer households but purchase a smaller quantity of higher quality (higher priced) goods. However, this seems a less likely cause. Table 1. for female-headed household 6-25: Estimation 191 Quality and measurement error effects in urban food demand of unit valuel Estimation of budget sharez Impact of Impact of expenditure unit value Prod elast F prob F prob SORGH -0.04 0.88 0.68 0.60 0.96 RICE -0.03 2.50 0.33 0.96 0.59 BREAD 0.02 0.56 0.83 1.55 0.12 CASSA 0.02 3.50 0.25 1.78 0.06 SWPOT 0.02 0.51 0.86 1.22 0.31 WHPOT -0.01 0.38 0.93 1.58 0.11 BANAN -0.02 0.10 1.00 0.73 0.87 CASFL 0.01 0.35 0.94 1.29 0.25 BEANS 0.02 0.43 0.90 0.68 0.91 PEAS -0.01 1.02 0.62 1.33 0.22 VEGET 0.05 1.88 0.41 0.66 0.92 BEEF 0.00 0.02 1.00 0.80 0.79 MEAT 0.05 1.02 0.62 1.85 0.05 MILK 0.02 1.14 0.58 1.57 0.11 BBEER -0.04 0.79 0.72 2.11 0.02 SBEER 0.03 1.58 0.47 1.37 0.20 FBEER -0.01 0.40 0.91 0.83 0.75 OIL -0.02 0.13 1.00 0.90 0.66 SALT -0.04 3.07 0.28 1.58 0.11 SUGAR 0.05 0.46 0.88 1.36 0.21 MEALS 0.23 7.77 0.12 1.14 0.38 Price (unit value) is expenditure squared, number cluster. 2. each sample cluster. regressed on log expenditure, of adults, and dummy variables for each sample number of children, log a dummy Budget share is regressed on log expenditure, log expenditure squared, number of adults, number of children, a dummy for female- headed households, prices (unit values), and dummy variables for The last two columns Table 6-24 give the F statistic and the corresponding probability under the null hypothesis that there are no "within cluster" price effects on budget share in the rural sector. The null hypothesis cannot be rejected at the 95% confidence level for 16 of the 17 equations; only sugar shows some "within cluster" effects which indicate measurement error effects. results from the urban demand model. The last two columns of Table 6-25 provide the corresponding In this case, the null hypothesis 192 cannot be rejected at the 95% level in 19 out of 21 equations; "other meat" and banana beer are the only goods which show signs of measurement error effects. In summary, although quality effects and measurement error may exist in the ENBC data, these tests indicate that they are not statisti- cally significant and that the quality elasticities are generally below 0.05. The measurement error is probably reduced by several factors. First, the ENBC involved 56 days of transaction data, thus including in many cases multiple observations for the same good and the same house- hold. The measurement error would be reduced by calculating the average unit value over several purchases. Second, because home prdduction is so important in the rural sector, many of the unit values for food were i, in fact average prices at the region—round level, again diluting i i measurement error. The small size of the quality effects is probably the result of the generally low level of income in Rwanda and the high degree of disaggregation in this demand study. For much of the population, additional income is allocated to increasing the quantity of food consumption rather than improving the quality. Nonetheless, the estimated elasticities are similar in magnitude to previous estimates. Using 1979 data from the C6te d'Ivoire, Deaton (1988) estimated quality elasticities which ranged from 0.023 to 0.065. Similarly, Deaton (1990) estimated quality elasticities from 1981 Indonesian data and obtained values from -0.04 to 0.22. Thus, it is possible that with a larger sample, some of the Rwandan quality elasticities may have been statisti- cally significant. CHAPTER SEVEN WELFARE AND NUTRITIONAL IMPACT OF DEVALUATION 7.1 Introduction This chapter uses information about household demand and the sources of household income to evaluate the welfare and nutritional effects of price changes associated with currency devaluation. In carrying out the simulation, various assumptions can be made about the supply response of agriculture and about the prices and wages associated with devaluation. In order to reduce the number of alternative scenari- os, a set of base assumptions is adopted, and the sensitivity analysis is limited to studying the effects of changing each assumption one at a time. In addition, various measures of welfare impact are compared. In the base scenario, household demand is simulated using the demand parameters estimated under the restrictions associated with consumer theory: adding up, symmetry, and homogeneity. The effect of price changes on income (the ”profit effect") is modeled using survey data on the composition of income, but no agricultural supply response is assumed. The price changes for both consumers and producers are hypothesized based on the tradeability of each good. Real wages are assumed to follow the average trend of other countries undergoing currency devaluation, as studied by Edwards (1989). And welfare impact is measured using equivalent variation (EV) and compensating variation (CV), calculated using the Vartia method with 20 iterations. The results of this base scenario are presented in section 7.2. Alternative scenarios will also be considered to determine the sensitivity of the results to changes in assumptions about demand, supply, prices, and wages. In section 7.3, the base scenario is compared to the simulated impact of the historical prices observed in Rwanda over the seven months following devaluation. Section 7.4 tests 193 194 the sensitivity of the results to alternative assumptions about real wage trends. Section 7.5 considers the implications of a more sophisti- cate model which incorporates agricultural supply response and a simpler model which ignores the profit effect completely. The last variant, presented in section 7.6, analyzes the results when the unrestricted parameters are used to model consumer demand. Finally, in section 7.7 we compare the various methods of calculating welfare impact, including consumer surplus, first- and second-order approximations of EV and CV, and two levels of precision in implementing the Vartia method. 7.2 Effects of hypothetical currency devaluation: base scenario 7.2.1 Assumption used in base scenario On November 20, 1990, the Rwandan franc was devalued 40%- relative to the International Monetary Fund Special Drawing Right. In other words, the local cost of foreign currency increased by two thirds (the inverse of 0.6 is 1.667). As discussed in section 4.2.5, we adopt the results of econometric analysis of devaluation episodes in 29 countries by Edwards (1989) and assume a rate of effectiveness of 0.6 in the first year after devaluation. Thus, a 67% increase in the local cost of foreign currency is translated into a increase in the ratio of tradeable to non-tradeable prices by 40%. In Rwanda, the tradeable food commodities are limited to rice, wheat products, cooking oil, sugar, and most processed foods. Factory beer and beans are intermediate cases. The beer uses imported malt, but these imports represent a small portion of the total cost to consumers (Haggblade, 1987). Beans are imported to Rwanda, but these imports represent perhaps 10-15% of national bean consumption. In addition, beans are imported informally so that devaluation affects bean prices only indirectly through its effect on the parallel exchange rate. For the purpose of this analysis, factory beer is considered 50% tradeable 195 and beans are considered 25% tradeable. These assumptions are summa- rized in Table 7-1. Table 7-1: Assumed tradeable component of each budget category IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-I-I-I-II-I-I-I-I-I-l Budget Tradeable component category Rural Urban SORGH 0.00 0.00 RICE 1.00 1.00 '— BREAD — 1.00 g CASSA 0.00 0.00 SWPOT 0.00 0.00 WHPOT 0.00 0.00 BANAN 0.00 0.00 CASFL - 0.00 BEANS 0.25 0.25 PEAS '0.00 0.00 TOMAT 0.00 - vscs'r 0.00 0.00 is BEEF 0.00 0.00 MEAT 0.00 0.00 MILK - 0.00 BBEER 0.00 0.00 SBEER 0.00 0.00 FBEER 0.50 0.50 OIL 1.00 1.00 SALT 0.00 0.00 SUGAR 1.00 1.00 MEALS - 0.00 CLOTH 0.96 0.94 HOUSE 0.14 0.16 EQUIP 0.64 0.76 ENERG 0.82 0.27 HEALT 0.50 0.73 EDUCA 0.34 0.16 TRANS 0.51 0.84 TOBAC 0.00 0.00 LEISU 0.51 0.30 OTHFO 0.10 0.21 For the non-food categories, a highly disaggregated list of non- food goods and services was classified into tradeable and non-tradeable. Then the proportion of expenditure on each category which goes to tradeable goods was calculated. The price of each non-food category was assumed to rise in proportion with the share of tradeable good expendi- ture in that category. This procedure was carried out separately in the 196 rural and urban areas to allow for the fact that the tradeable component of each non-food category varies somewhat between them. As shown in Table 7-1, among the non-food categories, the trade- able component is highest for clothing and lowest for tobacco. Not surprisingly, the tradeable component is greater among urban consumers than rural for household equipment, health/hygiene, and transportation. Presumably, the higher incomes of urban consumers make them more likely to purchase imported goods which are generally of a higher quality and more expensive. In contrast, the tradeable component is higher among rural consumers for educational expenditures. 'This is due to the large share of rural education spending which is allocated to school uniforms, which are classified as tradeable. Because private schools are more common in the cities, urban households spend a greater portion of educational expenses on school fees which are considered non-tradeable services. Similarly, rural energy/water spending has a higher tradeable component because of the importance of kerosenel; most urban spending on energy/water is allocated to charcoal and electrical services, both of which are classified as non-tradeable. In order to express the price changes in real terms, we normalize prices so that the budget share weighted average is 1.0. The result is that the price of pure non-tradeable goods and services falls about 7%, while that of pure tradeables rises by 30%. It is assumed that the percentage changes in price for a given commodity are the same through- out the countryz. 1. Firewood is the primary source of energy in the rural areas, but it is generally gathered by families for their own consump- tion. Information on firewood use is not available for this analysis. 2. Since transportation depends on tradeable goods (fuel and vehicles), we would expect marketing margins to increase somewhat following devaluation. A more sophisticated modelling approach would use data on the regional flows of goods and transportation costs to incorporate this effect. ‘ 197 On the income side, agricultural producer prices are assumed to change in proportion to the consumer prices of the same commodities. Similarly, beer brewer income is assumed to reflect banana beer prices. Coffee prices are assumed to follow tradeable good patterns. Although coffee prices have not risen since devaluation due to international price trends, this assumption reflects the fact that, in the absence of devaluation, local coffee prices would certainly have had to decline. '7 Regarding real wages, Edwards (1989: 335-336) analysis of devalua- tion episodes reveals that, on average, real agricultural wages fall 3.5%, while real non-agricultural wages decline 8.5% over the year following devaluation. These figures are adopted for artisanal, commer- cial, and wage income. These assumptions cover only 20% of net income 1 —I- IECTE e in rural areas, but they account for 92% of urban net income (see Table- 5-2). Thus, the impact of devaluation on urban income is fairly crudely modeled, so that the distributional results within the urban sector reflect primarily different expenditure patterns among households. As noted above, household demand in the base scenario is simulated using the demand parameters estimated under the restrictions of consumer theory: symmetry and homogeneity. These results were presented in sections 6.4 and 6.6. On the supply side, the base scenario assumes no agricultural supply response. This does not mean that there is no ”profit effect,” but rather that the profit effect is limited to the change in price multiplied by the original quantity of output. This can be considered an estimate of the short-term impact of price changes, before supply has time to adjust, or as a first-order estimate of the long-term impact of the price change (see section 3.4.1). 7.2.2 Aggregate demand and caloric intake The assumptions described in the previous section are used to simulate the change in income and prices affecting each house- hold in the sample, allowing us to predict the change in demand for each 198 household. In this section, the aggregate results for the rural and urban sectors are considered. Table 7-2 shows the change in mean budget shares resulting from the hypothesized price changes. These figures differ from those that would be obtained using the individual price elasticities presented in Chapter 6 for several reasons. First, these figures incorporate the effect of all prices, not just own-price, on demand for a given commodi- ty. Second, this table incorporates the "profit effect" in which prices influence income which in turn affects demand. Third, the elasticities in Chapter 6 are valid for a household "at the mean" but do not neces- sarily represent the response of aggregate demand to price changes. Finally, the estimated elasticities are applicable only for marginal changes in prices, whereas non-marginal changes are simulated here. It should be recalled that an increase (decrease) in budget share does not always correspond to an increase (decrease) in quantity demanded. For example, in the case of cooking oil, the budget share increases roughly 10% in response to a 30% increase in price; this implies a reduction in quantity demanded. The last two columns of Table 7-2 provide a rough indicator of the welfare impact of each price change on the expenditure side (the effect of price changes on agricultural income is not included in this mea- sure). CV1 is the first-order approximation of compensating variation expressed as percentage of household expenditure: the percentage price change times the old budget share. EVI, the first-order approximation of equivalent variation is similarly calculated except that the new budget share is used. These numbers show that, among the consumer price increases, the one with the most serious impact on rural welfare by far is the 30% increase in the price of clothing. This is particularly true when we consider that the welfare impact of changes in food prices is offset by simultaneous effects on agricultural income. 199 Table 7-2: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on rural demand — price budget share change (percent) CV1 EVl Prod (pct) old new (pct) (pct) SORGH -7.0 1.4 1.6 0.1 0.1 RICE 30.0 0.5 0.8 -0.1 -0.2 CASSA -7.0 5.9 6.0 0.4 0.4 SWPOT -7.0 12.5 12.4 0.9 0.9 WHPOT -7.0 4.0 4.6 0.3 0.3 BANAN -7.0 5.9 6.1 0.4 0.4 BEANS 2.0 21.6 22.0 -0.4 -0.4 PEAS -7.0 1.4 1.8 0.1 0.1 F“ TOMAT -7.0 0.1 0.2 0.0 0.0 BEEF -7.0 1.4 1.9 0.1 0.1 MEAT -7.0 1.9 2.0 0.1 - 0.1 BBEER -7.0 10.1 9.5 0.7 0.7 SBEER -7.0 3.9 3.9 0.3 -0.3 FBEER 11.0 0.8 0.8 -0.1 -0.1 OIL 30.0 1.0 1.1 -0.3 -0.3 SALT -7.0 1.0 0.9 0.1 0.1 SUGAR 30.0 0.3 0.2 -0.1 -0.1 . orsro -3.0 9.9 7.8 0.3 0.2 : CLOTH 29.0 6.3 6.4 -1.8 -1.8 HOUSE -2.0 3.3 3.3 0.1 0.1 EQUIP 17.0 1.5 1.4 -0.3 -0.2 ENERG 23.0 1.2 1.3 -0.3 -0.3 HEALT 12.0 1.7 1.7 -0.2 -0.2 EDUCA 5.0 0.4 0.4 -0.0 -0.0 TRANS 12.0 0.8 0.8 -0.1 -0.1 TOBAC -7.0 0.7 0.7 0.0 0.0 LEISU 12.0 0.4 0.4 -0.0 -0.0 TOTAL —0.1 100.0 100.0 0.1 -0.0 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. Table 7-3 focuses on food consumption and caloric intake. Price increases result in reduced demand for beans, factory beer, cooking oil, and sugar. However, this is more than offset by increased consumption of tubers and bananas, with the result that the volume of food consump- tion and caloric intake rise slightly. The aggregate impact of devaluation is simulated for the urban sector in the same manner as for the rural sector. Table 7-4 shows the mean budget shares among urban households before and after the relative price changes associated with devaluation. Higher prices reduce the average share allocated to rice, factory beer, cooking oil, sugar, 200 Table 7-3: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on rural food consumption price quantity consumed caloric intake change (kilograms/ae/yr) (kcal/ae/day) Prod (pct) old ‘ new % change old new % change SORGH -7.0 7.7 8.8 14.2 69.2 79.0 14.2 RICE 30.0 0.8 1.0 17.3 7.6 8.9 17.3 CASSA —7.0 72.1 76.5 6.2 333.6 354.3 6.2 SWPOT -7.0 208.4 211.8 1.6 439.6 446.8 1.6 WHPOT -7.0 43.7 51.1 16.9 79.1 92.5 16.9 BANAN -7.0 20.8 22.7 9.0 40.4 44.1 9.0 BEANS 2.0 92.2 89.6 -2.8 818.4 795.6 -2.8 PEAS -7.0 5.4 7.2 32.8 38.4 51.0 32.8 r— TOMAT -7.0 0.6 0.9 66.6 0.3 0.5 66.6 BEEF -7.0 1.8 2.5 38.4 10.9 15.1 38.4 ‘ MEAT -7.0 2.2 2.3 4.8 7.7 8.1 4.8 BBEER -7.0 51.9 50.2 -3.4 122.4 118.3 -3.4 SBEER -7.0 37.7 39.4 4.6 175.4 183.5 4.6 FBEER 11.0 1.2 '1.0 -18{4 1.6 1.3 -18.4 OIL 30.0 0.8 0.7 -16.1 22.6 18.9 -16.1 SALT -7.0 2.5 2.3 -11.6 0.0 0.0 -11.6 i SUGAR 30.0 0.6 0.3 -40.6 5.9 3.5 —40.6 E OTHFO -3.0 35.0 27.4 -21.7 114.0 89.3 -21.7 TOTAL -0.1 585.3 595.6 1.8 2287.1 2310.6 1.0 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. household equipment, and transportation. The last two columns of Table 7-4 indicate that the price increases in clothing and transportation have the greatest impact on the average urban household. Among the food categories, the most damaging price increases are those of sugar, cooking oil, and rice. By comparison, price increases in bread, beans, and factory beer are less important, at least to the average household. It is worth noting that urban prices rise by 4.4% using a base weighted average. Although prices were normalized for the country as a whole, the higher budget shares of tradeable goods among urban consumers mean that the weighted average price change is positive (reflecting the same pattern, the weighted average rural price change is slightly negative). 201 Table 7-4: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on urban demand —’ price budget share change (percent) CV1 EVl Prod (pct) old new (pct) (pct) SORGH —7.0 0.92 1.01 0.06 0.07 RICE 30.0 2.37 1.71 -0.71 -0.51 BREAD 30.0 0.67 0.73 -0.20 -0.22 CASSA -7.0 1.79 1.47 0.13 0.10 SWPOT -7.0 3.84 4.82 0.27 0.34 WHPOT -7.0 6.24 6.43 0.44 0.45 BANAN -7.0 2.93 2.84 0.20 0.20 CASFL -7.0 2.40 2.73 0.17 0.19 BEANS 2.0 10.37 11.35 -0.21 -0.23 PEAS -7.0 0.41 0.75 0.03 0.05 VEGET -7.0 1.57 1.45 0.11 0.10 BEEF -7.0 2.90 2.83 0.20 0.20 MEAT -7.0 2.11 2.25 0.15 , 0.16 MILK -7.0 2.30' 2.12 ' 0.16 0.15 BBEER -7.0 4.82 5.65 0.34 0.40 SBEER -7.0 1.16 1.35 0.08 0.09 FBEER 11.0 4.17 3.95 -0.46 -0.43 OIL 30.0 2.07 1.98 -0.62 -0.59 SALT -7.0 0.54 0.53 0.04 0.04 SUGAR 30.0 2.59 2.49 -0.78 -0.75 MEALS -7.0 2.76 3.16 0.19 0.22 OTHFO 1.0 5.69 4.53 -0.06 -0.05 CLOTH 28.0 5.50 5.43 -1.54 -1.52 HOUSE -1.0 10.04 9.89 0.10 0.10 EQUIP 21.0 2.87 2.48 -0.60 -0.52 ENERG 3.0 4.62 4.60 -0.14 -0.14 HEALT 20.0 3.05 3.00 -0.61 -0.60 EDUCA -1.0 1.07 1.09 0.01 0.01 TRANS 24.0 4.84 4.00 -1.16 -0.96 TOBAC -7.0 1.51 1.56 0.11 0.11 LEISU 4.0 1.88 1.80 -0.08 -0.07 TOTAL 4.4 100.00 100.00 . -4.38 -3.62 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. Table 7-5 concentrates on food demand and caloric intake in the urban areas. There appears to be substitution away from rice and bread and toward sweet potatoes, white potatoes, and cassava flour, as well as substitution away from factory beer and toward sorghum beer. The total volume of food consumption rises somewhat (2.8%), but the caloric intake falls slightly (1.1%). The fall in caloric intake is due primarily to the reduced consumption of cooking oil and rice. 202 Table 7-5: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on urban food consumption price quantity consumed caloric intake change (kilograms/ae/yr) (kcal/ae/day) Prod (pct) old new % change old new % change SORGH -7.0 8.71 9.59 10.11 78.50 86.44 10.11 RICE 30.0 11.38 5.95 -47.71 103.82 54.29 -47.71 BREAD 30.0 2.67 2.13 -20.06 29.25 23.38 -20.06 CASSA -7.0 21.74 16.48 -24.21 100.66 76.29 -24.21 SWPOT -7.0 70.56 97.46 38.14 148.86 205.63 38.14 WHPOT -7.0 150.64 158.45 5.18 272.43 286.53 5.18 BANAN -7.0 58.91 57.52 -2.35 114.60 111.90 -2.35 F7 CASFL -7.0 20.21 23.88 18.17 190.45 225.06 18.17 BEANS 2.0 65.05 69.00 6.07 577.49 612.56 6.07 . PEAS -7.0 2.95 5.46 85.09 20.78 38.45 85.09 VEGET -7.0 18.73 17.39 -7.18 12.83 11.91 -7.18 BEEF -7.0 10.88 10.77 -0.96 65.56 64.93 -0.96 MEAT -7.0 5.50 5.88 6.98. 19.44 20.80 6.98 MILK -7.0 7.33 6.68 -8.84 15.66 14.28 -8.84 BBEER -7.0 206.65 214.06 3.59 486.95 504.42 3.59 SBEER -7.0 20.87 25.29 21.19 97.20 117.80 21.19 ‘ FBEER 11.0 21.39 16.93 -20.87 29.31 23.19 -20.87 p- OIL 30.0 8.57 5.96 -30.47 234.81 163.26 -30.47 " SALT -7.0 3.25 3.20 -1.50 0.00 0.00 -1.50 SUGAR 30.0 13.54 9.37 -30.83 140.99 97.53 -30.83 MEALS -7.0 5.97 6.19 3.71 26.35 27.33 3.71 OTHFO 1.0 33.06 22.76 -31.14 102.36 70.48 -31.14 TOTAL 4.4 768.54 790.40 2.84 2868.29 2836.46 -1.11 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. 7.2.3 Distributional effegge of hypothetical devaluation Until this point, we have only considered the effects of the hypothetical devaluation on aggregate demand, food consumption, and caloric intake for the urban and rural sectors. In this section, the impact on different types of households will be considered. In this analysis, households are disaggregated by region, total expenditure (income), principal occupation, and sex of head of household. The welfare impact is calculated using the Vartia method to approximate the 203 equivalent variation (EV) and the compensating variation (CV). As mentioned above, the Vartia method is applied with 20 iterationsl. The welfare impact of price and income changes can be separated into the effect of changes in income and the effect of changes in consumer prices, as shown in section 3.4.4. The first component is the effect of the price changes on the household as producer, measured by producer surplusz. The second component is the impact on the house- , F; hold as consumer, measured as the CV or EV associated with the change in consumer pricesa. Combining the producer and consumer impact, we get the total welfare impact of the price and income changes. Table 746 shows the producer impact, the two measures of consumer impact, and the total impact of the hypothetical prices on different groups of households. For example, the value -3.5 under EV means that the price and income changes associated with devaluation are, on average, equivalent to a 3.5% decrease in the level of real expenditure (income) per adult equivalent. This figure is the sum of a negative producer impact (-4.0) and a smaller positive consumer impact (0.5). Similarly, the CV value of -3.6 means that, on average, compensation equal to 3.6% of their original level of expenditure would be necessary to make Rwandan households as well of as before devaluation. This result should be interpreted with some caution. The fact that the average impact is negative has little bearing on the desirabil- ity of devaluation as a policy option. First, as mentioned in Chapter 1. Price changes are divided into 20 increments and after each increment, household income is adjusted to compensate for the price change. Willingness to pay is approximated by the sum of these adjust- ments (Vartia, 1983). 2. In the base scenario, no supply response is assumed so the percentage change in producer surplus is simply the weighted average of output price increases, where the weights are the proportion of output from each source (see equation 3-31). 3. This is measured as the area under the compensated demand function, h(p,u), over the range of price movement (see equation 3-42). CV uses the "before" demand function, while EV uses the "after" func- tion. 204 Table 7-6: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on households Producer Consumer Consumer Net Net Pct change impact impact impact impact impact in caloric (PS) (EV-PS) (CV-PS) (EV) (CV) intake Sector Rural -3.8 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.3 Urban -7.8 -2.7 -3.5 -10.4 -1l.3 0.8 Mean -4.0 0.5 0.4 -3.5 -3.6 1.3 Expenditure quintile 1st -4.0 1.5 1.4 -2.5 -2.6 0.4 2d -4.0 1.0 0.9 -2.9 -3.0 0.7 3d -2.6 -0.0 -0.1 -2.6 -2.8 1.9 4th -4.3 0.7 0.6 -3.6 -3.8 0.7 5th ’ -5.1 -0.6 -0.9 -5.7 -6.0 2.6 Mean -4.0 0.5 0.4 -3.5 -3.6 1.3 Principal occupation Farmer -3.4 1.0 0.9 —2.5 -2.6 1.1 Artisan -6.5 -0.2 -0.5 -6.7 -7.0 1.5 Merchant -3.2 -1.6 -1.9 -4.8 ~5.1 2.3 Employee -6.9 -1.7 -2.2 -8.6 -9.1 2.7 Various -4.8 -0.1 -0.3 -4.9 -5.1 1.0 Mean -4.0 0.5 0.4 -3.5 -3.6 1.3 Sex of head of household Male -3.9 0.5 0.4 —3.4 -3.5 1.5 Female -4.5 0.5 0.4 -4.0 -4.1 0.5 Mean -4.0 0.5 0.4 -3.5 -3.6 1.3 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. 2, the pre-devaluation situation is generally unsustainable so that maintaining the original condition is not an option. Second, this model simulates only the short-term relative price effect, ignoring any impact on aggregate output and all long-term effects. Third, since price changes are expressed in relative terms, the negative impact is primari- ly a function of the assumption that real wages fall. In fact, given the size of the assumed drop in real wages, it is somewhat surprising that the average welfare impact is so modest. Turning our attention to the distributional effects, the first part of Table 7—6 makes it clear that, under the assumptions of the base scenario, the proportional reduction in real income due to currency devaluation is over three times as great for urban households as for rural households. For urban households, the prices associated with Ir 205 devaluation imply a 10% decline in standard of living on average. For their rural counterparts, the decline is only about 3%1. Rural house- holds face moderately lower incomes partially offset by small reductions in consumer prices. Urban households, by contrast, experience sharply reduced income, exacerbated by somewhat higher consumer pricesz. It is worth noting that these results overestimate the proportion- al impact on rural households to the extent that non-food home produc- tion (excluded from our calculation of expenditure) is important. As fi‘ noted in section 5.3.1, the value of collected firewood is probably the most significant component of rural non-food home production. Since non-food home production is likely to be much more important in the rural areas than in the cities, this omission also implies that, if m" v'a anything, the results in Table 7-6 understate the difference between rural and urban impact. Interestingly, the caloric impact is, on average, slightly positive, in spite of the reduction in real income. This may be the result of the fact that the food prices fall relative to non-food prices (see Tables 7-2 and 7-4). This, in turn, is a result of the greater tradeable component of non-food items compared to food (see Table 5-23). In addition, the tradeable food items whose prices increase (rice, bread, factory beer, and cooking oil) tend to be relatively expensive sources of calories compared to the non-tradeable staples (cassava, sweet potatoes, bananas, and so on). 1. Without some assumptions about the marginal utility of money for different households, we cannot say which group is "hurt" more by the price changes. For example, we cannot be sure that a 3% reduc- tion in the real income of a rural household would be less "painful" than a 10% reduction in the income of an urban household. Nonetheless, these figures provide useful information and contribute to a more informed application of the value judgements necessary to policy making. 2. The simulation assumes that the percentage price changes for a given commodity are equal or similar across households (compare Tables 7.2 and 7.4). However, the average price faced by a household is also a function of the composition of expenditure, which varies across households. Thus, saying that consumer prices rise more for urban households than rural means that they consume proportionately more of the (tradeable) goods whose prices increased. 206 The second part of Table 7-6 disaggregates the results by quintil- es of real expenditure per adult equivalent. This section indicates that the price changes associated with devaluation affect higher-income households more seriously than lower-income households. The percentage reduction in real income is more than twice as great for the richest 20% of households as for the poorest 20% of them. Although the patterns are not clear-cut, it seems that the richest fifth of Rwandan households purchase more tradeables and sell more non-tradeables as a proportion of income (expenditure) than other households. Given the weak relationship between the tradeable share of the budget and total.expenditure (see Tables 5—25 and 5-26), this pattern seems to be attributable to the greater market participation of high-income households. In other words, low income households are insulated from price changes by their relianCe on home production. With regard to principal occupation, farmers are the least affected by currency devaluation. Under the assumptions of the base scenario, households whose primary source of income is agriculture experience a 3% reduction in their standard of living, on average. These households account for 74% of all Rwandan households (see Table 5- 3). At the other extreme, wage earners are the most severely affected by devaluation. For the 6% of Rwandan households whose primary source of income is wage employment, the price changes associated with devalua- tion are equivalent to an 8.6% decline in real income. This is due to a large reduction in income and the fact that they purchase more tradeable goods, whose prices rise. It is worth noting that although non-agricultural income is assumed to fall 8.5%, the actual reduction in income among artisans, merchants, and employees ranges from 3.2% to 6.9%. The effect of wage reductions on household income is softened by the fact that most house- holds have other sources of income. 207 Given the common practice of using a small number of socio- professional categories to analyze the distributional aspects of policy, it is worth asking how much of the variation in welfare impact is captured by this type of classification. Analysis of variance was used to determine the proportion of the variance in EV which can be "ex- plained" by the principal occupation of the households. The results indicate that 50% of the variance occurs among occupations and 50% exists within each occupation. One implication of this result is that models which analyze policy impact using average characteristics of, say, half a dozen socio-professional categories may be ignoring 50% of the variation in welfare impact. .This suggests that the micro-simula- tion approach adopted in this study merits wider application when sufficient data are available. Table 7-6 also confirms, as a result of the price changes associ- ated with devaluation, that female-headed households experience a slightly greater percentage reduction in real income than male-headed households. This is the result of different sources of income rather than different spending patterns. Nonetheless, it is worth noting that the difference is not very great: devaluation is equivalent to a 4% decrease in real income for female-headed households and it is equiva- lent to a 3.4% decline in real income for male—headed households. At this point, we separate the rural and urban samples to analyze each one more closely. Table 7-7 shows the welfare impact on different categories of rural households. The first part of the table disaggrega- tes the households according to rural expenditure quintiles (the fifth quintile represents the 20% of rural households with the highest expenditure per adult equivalent). The negative effect of devaluation is greatest among the high-income households and lowest among the poorest. Both spending and income patterns appear to contribute to this result. 1} 208 Table 7-7: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on rural households Producer Consumer Consumer Net Net Pct change impact impact impact impact impact in caloric (PS) (EV-PS) (CV-PS) (EV) (CV) intake Rural expenditure quintile lst -3.9 1.5 1.4 -2.4 -2.5 0.4 2d -4.0 1.2 1.1 -2.8 -2.8 0.7 3d -2.7 -0.1 -0.3 -2.8 -2.9 2.0 4th -4.0 0.7 0.6 -3.3 -3.4 0.9 5th -4.5 0.1 -0.0 -4.4 -4.5 2.5 Mean -3.8 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.3 Region N West -4.5 1.0 0.8 -3.5 -3.7 2.0 S West -3.6 -0.0 '-0.1 -3.6 -3.8 1.8 N Centr -3.9 0.8 0.7 -3.1 -3.2— 0.4 S Centr -4.1 0.4 0.3 -3.7 -3.8 1.5 East -3.2 1.1 1.0 -2.2 -2.2 1.1 Mean -3.8 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.3 Principal occupation Farmer -3.4 1.0 0.9 -2.4 -2.5 1.1 Artisan -6.2 0.1 -0.1 -6.1 -6.3 1.6 Merchant -2.4 -l.2 -1.4 -3.6 -3.8 2.4 Employee -6.3 -0.7 -l.0 -7.0 -7.3 3.1 Various -4.6 0.0 -0.1 -4.6 -4.7 1.1 Mean -3.8 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.3 Sex of head of households Male -3.7 0.7 0.6 -3.0 -3.1 1.5 Female -4.4 0.7 0.5 -3.7 -3.8 0.7 Mean -3.8 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.3 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. The second section of Table 7-7 disaggregates rural households by region. These figures reveal that there is little geographic variation in the impact of devaluation, except that the East is less hurt than other rural regions. The Eastern zone is relatively low-density, drier area of the country. The farms in the East tend to be larger, averaging 2.0 hectares compared to 1.3 ha. for the country as a wholel. The East 1. These figures are from the Pilot Agricultural Census of 1982. Although average farm size has undoubtedly fallen since then, the East is still less densely populated than the rest of Rwanda. If a! (1 wk t1 IE 81‘: 01 t} 209 is even more specialized in agriculture than the rest of rural Rwanda, and it is the most important surplus producing area of the country (Ministry of Planning, 1988). The impression that farmers are relatively shielded from the impact of devaluation is confirmed in the third section of Table 7-7 which separates rural households by principal occupation. Farmers are the least affected, the welfare impact being equivalent to a 2.4% reduction in real expenditure. In contrast, the impact on salaried employees and artisans in the rural sector is over twice as great. Most of the difference between them is due to the sources of income rather than spending patterns. The last part of Table 7-7 breaks down the welfare impact by sex of head of household. The impact of devaluation is greater for female- headed households, although again the difference is rather small. Turning to the impact of prices associated with devaluation on urban households, Table 7-8 reveals many of the same patterns found in the rural sector. The relative effect of devaluation appears to be the most serious for high-income households, salaried employees, merchants, and residents of Kigali. The effect is less severe for the poor, farmers (about 14% of the "urban” households), and residents of Cities other than Kigali. In contrast to the rural results, there is little difference between male- and female-headed households in the urban sector; if anything, male-headed households are more severely affected by the prices associated with devaluation. 210 Table 7-8: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on urban households Producer Consumer Consumer Net Net Pct change impact impact impact impact impact in caloric (PS) (EV-PS) (CV-PS) (EV) (CV) intake Urban expenditure quintile lst -6.9 -0.6 -l.1 -7.6 -8.1 -2.2 2d -7.6 -1.5 -2.1 -9. -9.7 -3.1 3d -8.0 -3.2 -4.1 -11.2 -12.1 -0.6 4th -8.1 -4.4 -5.5 -12.5 -13.6 -0.3 Sth -8.3 -3.6 -4.6 -11.9 -12.9 10.0 Mean. -7.8 -2.7 -3.5 -10.4 -11.3 0.8 City Kigali -8.0 -2.9 -3.7 -10.9 -11.7 1.6 Other -7.1 -2.2 -2.9 -9.3 -10.0 -1.3 Mean -7.8 —2.7 -3.5 -10.4 -11.3 0.8 Principal occupation Farmer -6.0 -0.0 -0.4 -6.0 -6.4 -2.9 Artisan -8.2 -2.1 -2.8 -10.3 -11.0 1.1 Merchant -8.2 -3.9 -5.0 -12.1 -13.2 1.7 Employee -8.2 -4.0 -5.1 -12.2 -13.3 1.7 Various -7.0 -1.9 -2.6 -8.9 -9.6 0.5 Mean -7.8 -2.7 -3.5 -10.4 -11.3 0.8 Sex of head of household Male -7.9 -2.7 -3.5 -10.6 -11.4 1.4 Female -6.9 -2.7 -3.6 -9.7 -10.5 -2.5 Mean -7.8 -2.7 -3.5 -10.4 -11.3 0.8 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. 7.3 Effects of hietoricel pricefchanges This section analyzes the historical price changes associated with the November 1990 devaluation and simulates the effect of these changes on different types of households in Rwanda. This allows us to compare the hypothetical prices changes which "should have" accompanied devalua- tion with the price changes that actually occurred. In addition, it provides some information on changes in the standard of living among Rwandan households over the period 1989-1991 during which devaluation took place. 211 On the other hand, historical prices reflect not just the devalua- tion but also a variety of factors from seasonal cycles and economic policy to trends in international prices. This is a particular problem in the case of the Rwandan devaluation because it occurred just one month after an unsuccessful invasion of the country by rebels in Uganda. Security measures impeded the flow of goods and labor within the country, as well as restricting international trade through Ugandal. 7.3.1 General prige trends over 1989-1991 Using prices collected by the Ministry of Planning and the budget shares from the ENBC, a monthly consumer price index (CPI) was constructed for the period from October 1989 to June 1991. As shown in Figure 7-1, the CPI rose significantly in May and June 1989, declined gradually over the following year. This pattern probably reflects the crop failures in the south and southwest of Rwanda which led to scat- tered outbreaks of famine. In October 1990, the CPI increased sharply, rising 17% above the September level. Since the devaluation did not occur until 20 November, much of this increase would seem to be attrib- utable to the invasionz. Based on the limited data available, the October increase appears to have been a discrete increase in price level rather than an increase in the rate of inflation. The impact of devaluation can be observed by constructing separate indexes for tradeable and non-tradeable goods, as shown in Figure 7-2. This graph makes it Clear that the 1989 increase was principally the result of higher non-tradeable prices. Since this category is dominated by the starchy staples, this seems to confirm the idea that the 1989 increase was linked to the localized crop failure. Regarding the 1. In normal times, the most direct route to the coast is through Uganda to Mombassa, Kenya. As a result of attacks on trucks in Uganda, much of Rwandan overland trade is rerouted through Tanzania. 2. Although prices often increase in anticipation of devalu- ation, it should be noted that devaluation had been expected for over a year and yet the price hikes did not occur until November. I“ I 212 150 140 ’130 120 110 100 so 55" g 80 E 70 60 50 40 30 . 20 E;- 10 0 o N DJBSF u A M J J A s 0 N 0390: M A N J J A s 0 N 0351: M A M J Month Figure 7-1: Consumer price index for Rwanda (1989:100) October 1990 price increase, Figure 7-2 reveals that tradeable and non- tradeable prices increased in similar measure (14% and 17% respec- tively). However, the two indexes diverge substantially starting in November 1990. Non-tradeable prices fluctuate around the 110 level, while tradeable prices continue rising, reaching almost 130 by June 1991. From October 1990 to June 1991, the real exchange rate (RER), defined as the ratio of tradeable to non-tradeable prices, rose 31%. Given the 66.7% increase in the official cost of foreign exchange, this increase in the RER implies an effectiveness ratio of 47%, short of the 60% average calculated by Edwards (1989) and adopted for the hypo- thetical devaluation in section 7.2. However, Edwards’ figure repre- sented the average for the calendar year following devaluation, so more recent price data would be necessary to make an appropriate comparison. 213 150 140 130 420 100 90 80 Index 70 60 SO 40 3O 20 1O 0 0 N 0J89F M A M J J A S 0 N 0J90F M A M J J A S 0 N DJ91F N A M J Month D Tradeable prices Nontradeable prices Figure 7-2: Tradeable and nontradeable price indexes (1989=100) As noted above, historical prices are influenced by a variety of factors. The real exchange rate may have been affected by the war. For example, if internal security measures raised the prices of non-trade- able more than those of imports, the effect of devaluation on the RER would be dampened. On the other hand, if guerrilla activity in Uganda raised the price of tradeables disproportionately, the shift in RER may be strengthened by the war. Finally, it should be recalled that the import liberalization policies initiated at the end of 1990 probably dampened the effect of devaluation on the real exchange rate. 214 7.3-2 W In order to evaluate the impact of historical price changes on Rwandan households, the first step is to choose a "before" and "after" period. Because of the significant fluctuations in monthly prices, particularly those of agricultural commodities, it was decided to use a three-month average for both periods. To avoid the potential interference of seasonal patterns, it seemed preferable to compare the same quarter in two different years. Thus, the second quarter of 1990 was chosen to represent the situation before devaluation, while the second quarter of 1991 represents the prices after devaluation. These two periods are centered six months before and six months after November 1990 when the Rwandan franc was devalued. The food indexes are based on unpublished product-level prices for Kigali collected by the Office of Prices within the Ministry of Plan- ning. These prices, along with the average prices from the urban portion of the ENBC, are presented in Table 7-9. For the non-food categories, price indexes published by the Ministry of Planning (1991) were used. These indexes were calculated by Ministry personnel based on the prices of representative products and services within each category. These indexes are shown in Table 7-10. As in the hypothetical case, the producer prices of agricultural commodities are assumed to change in the same proportion as the Kigali consumer price for the same good. As before, agricultural wages are assumed to decline by 3.5% in real terms, while non-agricultural wages fall by 8.5% in real terms. Coffee and tea prices are assumed to remain constant in nominal terms. This reduction in real coffee prices is a delayed reaction to the fall in international coffee prices in the late 19803. Tables 7-9 and 7-10 bear little resemblance to the price changes expected on the basis of the tradeability of each budget category (see Table 7-2). Even taking into account the fact that the hypothetical Table 7-9: 215 Food prices in Kigali before and after devaluation IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-I-III-I-I-I-I-I-I-I-I Nominal prices (FRw/kg) ENBC/U May-July May-July % change Food category 1985 1989 1990 ’89-'90 Sorghum 22.9 33.7 45.3 34.7 Rice 90.2 109.3 122.0 11.6 Bread 65.4 50.0 54.3 8.7 Cassava 19.6 16.0 23.7 47.9 Cassava flour 34.1 43.7 50.3 15.3 Sweet potato 15.5 15.3 16.0 4.3 White potato 15.0 14.7 17.3 18.2 Banana 13.2 16.7 27.0 62.0 v Beans (dry) 48.4 36.0 42.7 18.5 F— Peas (dry) 51.2 65.3 59.0 -9.7 Groundnuts 143.9 125.3 148.0 18.1 Cabbage 17.2 12.0 13.7 13.9 Eggplant 32.0 26.0 29.7 14.1 Onion 60.7 80.7 128.7 59.5 Tomato ' 42.7 . 26.0 34.3 32.1 Beef 141.5 191.3 192.7 0.7 Goat meat 141.7 250.7 248.0 -1.1 Fish (indagala) 162.9 189.3 255.0 34.7 5_ Banana wine 29.7 45.7 50.7 10.9 I Sorghum beer 15.0 18.3 22.3 21.8 Factory beer 90.0 95.0 86.7 -8.8 Carbonated soda 24.7 28.3 37.0 30.6 Palm oil 156.0 159.3 180.0 13.0 Salt 55.7 48.3 65.0 34.5 Sugar 87.8 113.7 142.3 25.2 Prepared meal 55.3 127.3 116.0 -8.9 Source: Unpublished data collected by the Ministry of Planning. prices are normalized while the historical prices are not, it is clear that prices cannot be reliably predicted at this level of disaggrega- tion. Tradeable goods such as rice, beans, and factory beer registered modest increases, while some non-tradeable commodities such as bananas and cassava experienced sharp increases. There a number of possible explanations. First, these are Kigali prices so that the price increases for bananas and cassava may reflect in part the increased cost of transporting them to the capital (on the other hand, if this were a factor, we would expect the price of sweet potatoes to increase as well). Second, some prices were set by adminis- trative decision rather than by market forces. An initial increase in the government-set price of factory beer was rescinded when tax revenue 216 Table 7-10: Non-food prices in Kigali before and after devaluation — Price index (1989=100) Price 2d quart 2d quart change Budget category 1990 1991 (pct) Clothing 101.8 130.1 33.1 Household equipment 96.4 137.1 41.3 Energy 96.8 168.1 76.2 Water 101.5 101.5 2.4 Health 93.9 110.3 8.5 Hygiene 93.7 140.3 43.7 Education 109.4 133.3 31.1 Transport 94.1 117.8 23.7 F" Tobacco 122.7 148.6 21.1 Leisure/services 97.7 106.9 9.3 Source: Ministers du Plan, 1991. fell as a result. Another example is water and electricity rates, which ' i- were raised significantly to more closely reflect costs. This policy is part of the structural adjustment program but not a result of devalua- tion per 58. Third, it may be that there is simply too much natural variability in commodity prices to pick up the impact of devaluation at this level of disaggregation and in this short a period of time. It is worth recalling that when aggregated into tradeable and non-tradeable groups, the price trends follow the expected patterns. In spite of the divergence between anticipated price changes and the historical price trends, the model is run using historical prices. This simulation does not isolate the impact of devaluation, but it does give an idea of the probable effect on households of the all price changes that occurred over 1990-1991, regardless of their cause. 7.3.3 Aggregate demand and caloric intake The simulated effect of the historical price changes on rural budgets is shown in Table 7-11. The budget shares of cassava and bananas rise but by less than the increase in price, implying reduced quantity demanded. The share allocated to factory beer rises signifi- cantly, though starting from a very low base. The non-food budget shares are relatively unaffected by the price changes. According to the 217 last two columns in Table 7-11, the most serious impact on rural households as consumers were caused by the large price increase for bananas and the more moderate increase in bean prices. However, it should be noted that the welfare impact of these price changes is offset by their influence on rural households as producers. Among non-food categories, the increase in clothing price has the greatest effect on rural households. In ’J ’1 f1 218 Table 7-11: Effect of historical price changes on rural budgets price budget share change (percent) CV1 EVl Prod (pct) old new (pct) (pct) SORGH 34.7 1.4 1.6 -0.5 -0.5 RICE 11.6 0.5 0.3 -0.1 -0.0 CASSA 47.9 5.9 6.0 -2.8 -2.9 SWPOT 4.3 12.5 12.4 -0.5 -0.5 WHPOT 18.2 4.0 3.7 -0.7 -0.7 BANAN 62.0 5.9 6.6 -3.6 —4.1 BEANS 18.5 21.6 23.0 -4.0 -4.3 PEAS -9.7 1.4 1.4 0.1 0.1 TOMAT 32.1 0.1 0.1 -0.0 -0.0 BEEF 0.7 .1.4 0.8 -0.0 --0.0 MEAT -0.2 1.9 2.7 0.0 0.0 BBEER 10.9 10.1 9.0 -1.1 -1.0 SBEER 21.8 3.9 3.4 -0.9 -0.7 FBEER -8.8 0.8 2.0 0.1 0.2 OIL 30.6 1.0 0.6 -0.3 -0.2 SALT 34.5 1.0 0.6 -0.4 -0.2 SUGAR 25.2 0.3 0.5 -0.1 -0.1 OTHFO 23.0 9.9 9.5 -2.3 -2.2 CLOTH 33.1 6.3 6.2 -2.1 -2.1 HOUSE 23.0 3.3 3.1 -0.8 -0.7 EQUIP 41.3 1.5 1.4 -0.6 -0.6 ENERG 76.2 1.2 1.4 -0.9 -1.0 HEALT 8.5 1.7 1.6 -0.1 -0.1 EDUCA 31.1 0.4 0.4 -0.1 -0.1 TRANS 23.? 0.8 0.8 —0.2 -0.2 TOBAC 21.1 0.7 0.7 -0.1 -0.1 LEISU 9.3 0.4 0.4 -0.0 -0.0 TOTAL 22.1 100.0 100.0 -22.1 -22.2 (mu-Ema Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. Table 7-12 presents the aggregate changes in the quantity of food consumed and caloric intake by rural households. There is substitution away from cassava, white potatoes, and bananas, whose prices rose significantly, and toward beans and sweet potatoes, whose price increas- es were more modest. The price increase of cassava has the greatest negative impact on caloric intake, but this is offset by increased reliance on beans. The net effect is that the volume of food consump- tion and caloric intake fall by less than 2%. The small size of the 219 fall in caloric intake is due to the fact that participation in the market is limited. In addition, the increases in food prices are offset by increased revenue for surplus food producers. Table 7-12: Effect of historical prices on rural food consumption — price quantity consumed caloric intake change (kilograms/ae/yr) (kcal/ae/day) ”a. Prod (pct) old new % change old new % Change SORGH 34.7 7.7 7.3 -4.3 69.2 66.2 -4.3 RICE 11.6 0.8 0.5 —38.5 7.6 4.7 -38.5 p CASSA 47.9 72.1 58.6 -18.7 333.6 271.1 -18.7 SWPOT 4.3 208.4 224.6 7.8 439.6 . 473.9 7.8 F WHPOT 18.2 43.7 39.0 -10.7 79.1 70.6 -10.7 f BANAN 62.0 20.8 17.8 -14.5 40.4 34.6 -14.5 ' BEANS 18.5 92.2 97.8 6.1 818.4 868.6 6.1 . PEAS -9.7 5.4 6.9 25.9 38.4 48.3 25.9 _ TOMAT 32.1 0.6 0.4 -21.0 0.3 0.2 -21.0 r: BEEF 0.7 1.8 1.2 -36.3 10.9 6.9 -36.3 MEAT -0.2 2.2 3.4 55.4 7.7 12.0 55.4 BBEER 10.9 51.9 49.2 -5.3 122.4 115.9 -5.3 SBEER 21.8 37.7 30.7 -18.4 175.4 143.1 -18.4 FBEER -8.8 1.2 2.9 143.2 1.6 4.0 143.2 OIL 30.6 0.8 0.5 -44.2 22.6 12.6 -44.2 SALT 34.5 2.5 1.4 -46.1 0.0 0.0 -46.1 SUGAR 25.2 0.6 0.7 27.9 5.9 7.5 27.9 OTHFO 23.0 35.0 31.4 -10.1 114.0 102.5 -10.1 TOTAL 22.1 585.3 574.3 -1.9 2287.1 2242.7 -1.9 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. The simulated impact of historical price changes on urban budgets is shown in Table 7-13. On average, prices increased about 20% in the urban areas. The shifts in budget allocations seem to be driven more by reductions in real income than by the individual price changes. Larger shares of the budget are spent on necessities such as beans, sweet potatoes, cassava root, and cassava flour, while smaller shares are allocated to luxuries such as factory beer, rice, bread, sugar, and most non-food categories. The price increases which put the largest dent in urban living standards are those of energy/water, housing, beans, and clothing. 220 Table 7-13: Effect of historical price changes on urban budgets _ price budget share change (percent) CV1 EVl Prod (pct) old new (pct) (pct) SORGH 34.7 0.9 0.9 -0.3 -0.3 RICE 11.6 2.4 1.9 -0.3 -0.2 BREAD 8.7 0.7 0.5 -0.1 -0.0 CASSA 47.9 1.8 2.3 -0.9 -1.1 SWPOT 4.3 3.8 4.1 -0.2 -0.2 WHPOT 18.2 6.2 8.2 -1.1 -1.5 BANAN 62.0 2.9 2.5 -1.8 -1.6 CASFL 0.0 2.4 2.8 0.0 0.0 BEANS 18.5 10.4 11.8 -1.9 -2.2 PEAS -9.7 0.4 0.5 0.0 0.1 VEGET 0.0 1.6 1.4 0.0 0.0 BEEF 0.7 2.9 3.1 -0.0 -0.0 MEAT -0.2 2.1 1.9 0.0 0.0 MILK 0.0 2.3 1.9 0.0 0.0 BBEER 10.9 4.8 5.4 -0.5 -0.6 SBEER 21.8 1.2 1.2 -0.3 -0.3 FBEER -8.8 4.2 4.0 0.4 0.3 OIL 30.6 2.1 2.0 -0.6 -0.6 SALT 34.5 0.5 0.6 -0.2 -0.2 SUGAR 25.2 2.6 2.4 -0.7 -0.6 MEALS -8.9 2.8 2.9 0.2 0.3 OTHFO 23.0 5.7 6.0 -1.3 -1.4 CLOTH 33.1 5.5 5.3 -1.8 -1.8 HOUSE 23.0 10.0 8.6 -2.3 -2.0 EQUIP 41.3 2.9 2.3 -1.2 -1.0 ENERG 76.2 4.6 3.7 -3.5 -2.8 HEALT 8.5 3.1 3.0 -0.3 -0.3 EDUCA 31.1 1.1 1.0 -0.3 -0.3 TRANS 23.7 4.8 4.2 -1.1 -1.0 TOBAC 21.1 1.5 1.6 -0.3 -0.3 LEISU 9.3 1.9 1.8 ~0.2 -0.2 TOTAL 20.5 100.0 100.0 -20.5 -19.7 Table 7-14 concentrates on the effect of the historical price changes on urban food consumption. In caloric terms, the largest reductions in consumption are those of bananas, cooking oil, and sugar, but this is offset by increase caloric intake from white potatoes, cassava flour, and beans. The net effect is that urban caloric intake declines by less than 3%. 221 Table 7-14: Effect of historical prices on urban food consumption — price quantity consumed caloric intake change (kilograms/ae/yr) (kcal/ae/day) Prod (pct) old new % change old new % change ’SORGH 34.7 8.7 6.1 -30.4 78.5 54.6 -30.4 RICE 11.6 11.4 8.4 -25.9 103.8 76.9 -25.9 BREAD 8.7 2.7 1.9 -29.6 29.2 20.6 -29.6 CASSA 47.9 21.7 23.4 7.5 100.7 108.2 7.5 SWPOT 4.3 70.6 73.2 3.7 148.9 154.4 3.7 WHPOT 18.2 150.6 184.7 22.6 272.4 334.0 22.6 BANAN 62.0 58.9 31.1 -47.2 114.6 60.5 -47.2 CASFL 0.0 20.2 25.0 23.8 190.5 235.7 23.8 BEANS 18.5 65.1 69.6 7.1 577.5 618.3 7.1 PEAS -9.7 3.0 4.3 45.1 20.8 >30.1 45.1 VEGET 0.0 18.7 17.5 -6.7 12.8 12.0 -6.7 BEEF '0.7 10.9 >12.1 11.1 65.6 72.8 11.1 MEAT -0.2 5.5 5.0 -10.0 19.4 17.5 -10.0 MILK 0.0 7.3 6.0 -17.5 15.7 12.9 -17.5 BBEER 10.9 206.6 192.9 -6.7 486.9 454.5 -6.7 SBEER 21.8 20.9 19.4 -7.2 97.2 90.2 -7.2 FBEER -8.8 21.4 22.5 5.4 29.3 30.9 5.4 OIL 30.6 8.6 6.8 -20.4 234.8 186.8 -20.4 SALT 34.5 3.2 3.0 -6.2 0.0 0.0 -6.2 SUGAR 25.2 13.5 10.2 -24.9 141.0 105.9 -24.9 MEALS -8.9 6.0 6.5 9.3 26.4 28.8 9.3 OTHFO 23.0 33.1 28.5 -13.8 102.4 88.2 -13.8 TOTAL 20.5 768.5 758.1 -1.4 2868.3 2794.0 -2.6 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. 7.3.4 Distributional effects of historical price Changes This section considers the effect of the historical price changes on different groups of households. As explained above, the welfare and caloric impact are calculated for each household in the sample and then averaged over the household category. Table 7-15 presents the producer impact, the two measures of consumer impact, and the net impact, as well as the percentage change in caloric intake for each group. The net effect of the price changes between the second quarter of 1990 and a year later is equivalent, for the average household, to a reduction in real income of 4.7%. Compensation of 5.8% of household Table 7-15: 222 Effect of historical price changes on households Producer Consumer Consumer Net Net Pct change impact impact impact impact impact in caloric (PS) (EV-PS) (CV-PS) (EV) (CV) intake Sector Rural 16.2 -20.3 -21.4 -4.1 -5.1 -2.5 Urban 1.4 -16.0 -19.1 -14.6 -17.8 0.8 Mean 15.5 -20.1 -21.3 -4.7 -5.8 -2.3 Expenditure quintile lst 16.7 -20.2 -21.2 -3.6 -4.5 -3.3 2d 16.7 -20.0 -20.8 -3.3 -4.1 -2.6 3d 15.8 -20.7 -22.0 -5.0 -6.3 -2.8 4th 16.0 -20.5 -21.6 -4.5 -5.6 -3.0 5th 12.1 -19.1 -20.6 -6.9 -8.5 -0.2 Mean 15.5 -20.1 -21.3 -4.7 -5.8 -2.3 Principal occupation Farmer 17.2 -20.7 ~21.5 -3.4 —4.3 -2.2 Artisan 10.6 -19.2 -21.2 -8.6 -10.6 -3.3 Merchant 12.1 -17.5 -18.8 -5.4 -6.7 -3.1 Employee 4.4 -16.4 -19.1 -12.0 -14.7 -2.2 Various 15.0 ~20.4 -21.7 -5.3 -6.6 -2.1 Mean 15.5 ~20.1 -21.3 -4.7 -5.8 -2.3 Sex of head of household Male 15.2 -20.0 -21.1 -4.8 —6.0 -2.3 Female 16.6 -20.7 -21.8 -4.1 -5.1 -2.4 Mean 15.5 -20.1 -21.3 -4.7 -5.8 -2.3 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. expenditure would be necessary to restore the original living standard. However, this figure varies considerably from one type of household to another. The relative impact on urban households is over three times as great as the impact on rural households (the absolute equivalent variation or compensating variation would be much greater). Most of this difference is due to the fact that urban income, based heavily on wages and services, rises only slightly (1.4%). By contrast, a large portion of rural incomes is tied to commodity prices and rise signifi- cantly (16%). The second part of Table 7-15 divides households according to the level of expenditure per adult equivalent. These results indicate that low-income households are much less affected by the price changes over 223 1990-91 than high-income households. For the poorest 20% of the households, the price changes were equivalent to a 3.6% reduction in real income, while for the richest 20%, they were equivalent to a 6.9% reduction. This difference is due primarily to the relative importance of different sources of income rather than to the composition of expenditure. The third part of the table disaggregates the households by principal occupation. Again, employees are the hardest hit, and farmers are relatiVely insulated from the price changes. This is consistent with the quintile results since salaried workers earn high incomes on. average, while farmers tend to be the poorest segment of the population. Finally, male-headed households appear to have been more affected é by the price trends than female-headed households, although the differ- ences are quite modest. In the interest of space, the rural and urban results will not be presented here. However, it is worth briefly reviewing some of the results. In the rural areas, the households least affected by the historical price changes were poor households, farmers, and those in the Eastern zone. Employees were particularly hard hit. In the urban areas, poor households are again less affected than others (though the relationship is weaker than in the rural sector). Farmers and urban residents outside Kigali were also relatively protected from the price changes. Differences in impact according to the sex of head of house- hold were weak or non-existent. Thus, in spite of the fact that the historical price trends were quite different than the expected "hypothetical" price changes, the results of the simulation in terms of distributional impact were quite similar. One possible explanation is that the similarity is due to the wage assumptions, which were the same in the two simulations. An alternative explanation is that semi-subsistence households (and by 224 extension, poor households) are somewhat insulated from price changes by virtue of their limited participation in the market. 7.4 Wage rate assumptions As described in section 5.2, only 6% of Rwandan households depend on wages for a majority of their income, but over half of both urban and rural households have some wage income. This section tests the hypothe- sis that the results obtained in sections 7.2 and 7.3 were primarily the result of the assumption that real wages decline. In particular, the greater impact of devaluation on high income households may have resulted from the assumption that real wages fall, since wages are an important source of income for these households. The base scenario of is rerun except that now it is assumed that wages and salaries are held constant in real terms. Table 7-16 shows the welfare and caloric impact of the hypotheti- cal devaluation with nominal wages allowed to rise at the same level as commodity prices. Not surprisingly, both urban and rural households are better off in this simulation than in the base scenario. The effect of the hypothetical devaluation is equivalent to a 1.7% increase in real income for the average Rwandan household. Once again, urban households are more negatively affected than rural households: the impact for rural households is equivalent to a 2% increase in real income, while for urban households it is equivalent to a 4% decrease in real income. The table reveals that urban incomes fall while urban consumer prices rise, whereas in the rural sector average income increases while average prices fall. Another way to express this is that urban income is more heavily dependent on non-tradeables (particularly services) than rural income, and urban spending is more heavily weighted to tradeable goods (particularly non-food spending) than rural spending. The second part of Table 7-16 divides households according to their expenditure quintile. As in previous scenarios, the poorest Table 7-16: Effect of hypotheticalzzdsevaluation on households assuming real wage remains constant — Producer Consumer Consumer Net Net Pct change impact impact impact impact impact in caloric (PS) (EV-PS) (CV-PS) (EV) (CV) intake Sector Rural 1.3 0.7 0.6 2.0 1.9 4.6 Urban -1.1 -3.1 -3.5 -4.1 -4.6 3.1 Mean 1.2 0.5 0.4 1.7 1.6 4.5 Expenditure quintile 1st 1.0 1.4 1.4 2.5 2.4 4.4 2d 1.1 1.0 0.9 2.1 2.1 4.4 3d 2.2 -0.1 -0.1 2.1 2.0 4.9 4th 0.8 0.7 0.6 1.5 1.4 4.1 5th 0.9 -0.7 -0.9 0.1 -0.0 4.9 Mean 1.2 0.5 _0.4 1.7 1.6 4.5 Principal occupation Farmer 1.4 1.0 0.9 2.4 2.3 4.4 Artisan 0.3 -0.4 -0.5 -0.1 -0.2 5.0 Merchant 2.1 -1.8 -1.9 0.3 0.2 5.1 Employee -0.0 -2.0 -2.2 -2.0 -2.3 5.3 Various 0.5 -0.2 -0.3 0.3 0.2 4.1 Mean 1.2 0.5 0.4 1.7 1.6 4.5 Sex of head of household Male 1.4 0.5 0.4 1.8 1.7 4.7 Female 0.5 0.5 0.4 1.0 0.9 3.9 Mean 1.2 0.5 0.4 1.7 1.6 4.5 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. households are the least harmed by the hypothetical price changes. In this case, the price changes are equivalent to a 2.5% increase in real income. As household expenditure rises, the benefits of the hypotheti- cal devaluation decline, until they are essentially zero for the richest 20% of households. The third part of Table 7-16 separates households according to the principal occupation. As in the base scenario, employees are the most seriously affected by the price and income changes, while farmers are the least negatively affected. In this case, farmers actually gain from the hypothetical devaluation. The other occupations remain in an intermediate position, neither gaining nor losing. 226 According to the last section of Table 7-16, male-headed house- holds benefit more under this scenario than female-headed households. The table also indicates that the difference is due to income patterns rather than to spending patterns. This result is probably related to the fact that wage income is less common for female-headed households than for male-headed households. Most of these patterns are repeated in the rural and urban sub- samples (see Appendix X). In the rural sector, the poor benefit the most and the rich the least from this devaluation scenario. In the cities, the pattern is lees Clear, but the poorest 40% are certainly less negatively affected than the rest of the urban population. In summary, most of the patterns observed in the base scenario and the historical price scenario have been repeated in this simulation with real wages held constant. Thus, these results appear not to be due simply to the real wage assumptions. Rather, they seem to be a reflec- tion of the different spending and income patterns among Rwandan households. 7.5 Supply pesponse assumptions In the base scenario, the producer impact (the effect of prices on income) is simply the change in price multiplied by the level of output. This can be described as a first-order estimate of producer surplus or the short-term effect of prices on income. In this section, we consider the sensitivity of the results to changes in the way the effects on producers are specified. The first question is whether it is important to include the producer impact at all. Brief inspection of Tables 7-6 and 7-15 make it clear that ignoring the producer impact would seriously distort the results. This is particularly true when nominal price changes are modeled since the implicit assumption behind omitting the producer impact in this case is that nominal income remains constant. For exam sirm the the: O. (D k?) that real unde simu demo the 227 example, if we ignored the producer impact in the historical price simulation of Table 7-15, we would conclude that the welfare effect of the price changes was equivalent to a 20% fall in real income rather than the actual figure of less than 5%. Omitting the producer impact is probably less distorting when deflated prices are used, since in this case the implicit assumption is that real income is constant. 0n the other hand, to the extent that real wages tend to fall as a result of devaluation, this procedure would underestimate the negative effect. For example, the base scenario simulates a hypothetical devaluation using normalized prices. Table 7-6 demonstrates that the consumer effect gives an overly optimistic view of the net effect of the price changes. The next question concerns the possible improvement in the simulation by incorporating supply response. In the medium- to long- term, producers adapt to price changes, substituting away from goods whose prices have declined and toward those with higher returns. Clearly, a model which incorporates supply response will generate a more positive (or less negative) welfare impact than one which holds output constant. But it is an empirical issue whether the magnitude of this change is important. Ansoanuur (1991) estimated the supply elasticities for a number of agricultural commodities. The elasticities ranged from 0.02 for bananas to 1.92 for the long-run response of coffee, as shown in Table 7-17. Since these elasticities were estimated using deflated prices, the supply response was calculated using the relative price Changes of agricultural commodities. In carrying out these calculations for each household, we assume that the supply elasticity of each household is the same, and that each household changes the output of existing crops but ‘17 '.- l! ‘rlt-nfle .v. '. e) 5: ir. 228 Table 7-17: Estimated agricultural supply elasticities Estimated supply Crop elasticity Sorghum 0.167 Rice 0.069 Cassava 0.121 Sweet potatoes 0.081 White potatoes 0.394 Bananas 0.018 Beans 0.094 Coffee (short term) _ 0.385 Coffee (long term) 1.925 Tea (short term) 0.046 Tea (long term) 0.250 Source: Ansoanuur (1991). does not change the crop mixl. Since supply response information is only available for agricul- tural commodities, the analysis in this section will focus on the rural sector. Table 7-18 shows the distributional impact of the hypothetical devaluation on rural households with agricultural supply response as estimated by Ansoanuur (1990). Comparing this table with Table 7-7 from the base scenario (without supply response), it appears that the introduction of these supply elasticities makes virtually no difference in the results. The average producer impact is -3.7% of household expenditure, only a very slight improvement from -3.8% in the base scenario. The other sets of corresponding figures are equal close or indistinguishable at this level of precision. Certainly part of the explanation for the fact that incorporating these supply elasticities has virtually no effect on the results is that the elasticities are quite small, particularly for beans, sweet pota- toes, and bananas. Thus, another simulation was run setting all the agricultural supply elasticities to 1.0. In view of agricultural supply 1. This assumption is a necessary result of using time- series data to model supply response. Modeling crop mix would require cross-sectional data, perhaps in conjunction with a tobit model. 229 response studies from other less developed countries, this probably represents an probably upper bound for the actual supply elasticities. Table 7-18: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on rural households, assuming medium agricultural supply elasticities IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-II-I-I-I-I-IIIIIIIII-I Producer Consumer Consumer Net Net Pct change impact impact impact impact impact in caloric (PS) (Ev-PS) (CV-PS) (EV) (CV) intake Rural expenditure quintile 1st -3.9 1.5 1.4 -2.4 -2.4 0.6 2d -3.9 1.2 1.1 -2.7 -2.8 0.8 3d -2.6 -0.2 -0.3 -2.7 -2.8 2.3 4th ~3.9 0.7 0.6 -3.2 -3.3 1.0 5th -4.4 0.1 -0.0 -4.3 -4.5 2.3 Mean -3.7 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.4 Region N West -4.4 1.0 0.8 -3.5 -3.6 1.8 S West -3.5 -0.0 -0.1 -3.6 -3.7 2.0 N Centr -3.8 0.8 0.7 -3.0 -3.1 0.6 S Centr -4.0 0.4 0.3 -3.6 -3.7 1.8 East -3.1 1.1 1.0 -2.1 -2.1 1.3 Mean -3.7 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.4 Principal occupation Farmer -3.3 1.0 0.9 -2.4 -2.4 1.3 Artisan -6.1 0.1 -0.1 -6.1 -6.3 1.6 Merchant -2.2 -1.2 -1.4 -3.5 -3.6 2.8 Employee -6.3 -0.7 -1.0 -7.0 -7.3 3.1 Various -4.6 0.0 -0.1 -4.5 -4.7 1.2 Mean -3.7 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.4 Sex of head of household Male —3.6 0.7 0.6 -2.9 -3.0 1.6 Female -4.4 0.7 0.5 -3.7 -3.8 0.6 Mean -3.7 0.7 0.6 -3.1 -3.2 1.4 ' Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. Table 7-19 shows the simulated impact of a hypothetical devalua- tion with agricultural supply elasticities set at 1.0. Again comparing the results to the base scenario presented in Table 7-7, the incorpora- tion of an elastic supply response reduces the average producer impact from -3.8% of household expenditure to -3.5%. The net impact, as measured with equivalent variation, declines from -3.1% without supply response to -2.8% with supply response. Of course, the position of 230 farmers relative to other occupations improves since it is only agricul- tural production that is allowed to respond to price changes in this simulation. But all of the basic patterns with respect to expenditure quintile, region, occupation, and sex of head of household remain essentially unchanged. Table 7-19: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on rural households, assuming high agricultural supply elasticities Producer Consumer Consumer Net Net Pct change impact impact impact impact impact in caloric (PS) (EV-PS) (CV-PS) (EV) (CV) intake Rural expenditure quintile 1st -3.7 1.5 1.4 -2.2 —2.3 0.2 2d -3.7 1.2 1.1 -2.5 -2.6 0.3 3d -2.3 -0.1 -0.3 -2.4 -2.5 2.5 4th -3.8 0.7 0.6 -3.0 -3.1 0.6 5th -4.2 0.2 -0.0 -4.1 -4.3 1.8 Mean -3.5 0.7 0.6 -2.8 -3.0 1.1 Region N West -4.2 1.0 0.8 -3.2 -3.4 1.9 S West -3.2 -0.0 —0.1 -3.3 -3.4 1.9 N Centr -3.7 0.8 0.7 -2.8 -2.9 0.1 S Centr -3.9 0.5 0.3 -3.4 -3.6 1.2 East -2.9 1.1 1.0 -1.8 -1.9 0.9 Mean -3.5 0.7 0.6 -2.8 -3.0 1.1 Principal occupation Farmer —3.1 1.0 0.9 -2.1 -2.2 1.0 Artisan —6.1 0.1 —0.1 -5.9 -6.2 1.2 Merchant -1.9 -1.2 -1.4 -3.2 -3.3 2.7 Employee -6.2 -0.7 -l.0 -6.9 -7.2 2.7 Various -4.4 0.1 -0.1 -4.4 -4.5 0.5 Mean -3.5 0.7 0.6 -2.8 —3.0 1.1 Sex of head of household Male -3.4 0.7 0.6 -2.7 -2.8 1.4 Female -4.2 0.7 0.5 —3.5 -3.7 -0.1 Mean -3.5 0.7 0.6 -2.8 -3.0 1.1 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. In summary, the effect of incorporating agricultural supply response into the simulation is modest to negligible. Even with agricultural production is assumed to be quite responsive to price, the distributional patterns of the hypothetical devaluation are not affect- 1F" 231 ed. Although incorporating some kind of producer impact is critical in such a model, it appears that a first-order approximation of producer surplus is sufficient for most purposes. 7.6 Demand response essumptions In the base scenario, demand was modeled using the parameters estimated under the restrictions of consumer theory. It is worth asking whether the results change appreciably when the unrestricted demand parameters are used instead. These demand parameters, and their corresponding price and income elasticities, are described in sections 6.3 and 6.5. Table 7-20 indicates that the consumer effect and hence the net impact is somewhat greater, in absolute value, when the unrestricted demand model is adopted. This presumably reflects the fact that imposing symmetry made demand somewhat more price responsive, allowing greater adaptation on the part of consumers to changes in price. Nonetheless, all the basic results obtained when using the restricted model hold as well when the unrestricted model is adopted. The relative insensitivity of the results to changes in demand response is illustrated by the considering the extreme case when there is no demand response. If compensated demand is perfectly inelastic, then the area under the curve (willingness to pay) is simply the original quantity times the price change. This is equal to_the first- order approximation of compensating variation for an arbitrary demand system. Thus, we can use CV1 under the base scenario to indicate the exact compensating variation in the extreme case in which consumer demand is completely inflexible. As shown in Table 7-21, CV1 is greater (in absolute magnitude) than the other welfare measures. At the same time, CV1 is closely correlated with the other measures, in the sense that it gives the same results regarding the relative impact on rural and urban households, 232 rich and poor households, and so on. In other words, the results concerning the relative impact of devaluation on different households are fairly insensitive to the responsiveness of demand to price changes. Table 7-20: Effect of hypothetical devaluation on households using the unrestricted demand model lIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII-Il-I-I-I-II-I-I-I-II Producer Consumer Consumer Net Net Pct change impact impact impact impact impact in caloric (PS) (EV-PS) (CV-PS) (EV) (CV) intake Sector a Rural -3.8 0.8 0.7 -3.0 -3.1 -1.7 1 Urban -7.8 -2.6 -3.5 -10.4 -11.3 2.2 i Mean -4.0 0.7 0.5 -3.4 -3.6 -1.5 1 Rural expenditure quintile lst —4.0. 1.6 1.5 -2.4 -2.5 -3.1 1: 2d -4.0 1.2 1.0 -2.8 -2.9 -1.8 3d -2.6 0.1 -0.0 -2.5 -2.7 -1.1 4th -4.3 0.8 0.7 -3.5 -3.7 -2.6 5th -5.1 -0.5 -0.9 -5.6 -6.0 1.0 Mean -4.0 0.7 0.5 -3.4 -3.6 -1.5 Principal occupation Farmer -3.4 1.1 1.0 -2.3 -2.5 -2.1 Artisan -6.5 -0.1 -0.4 -6.6 -6.9 -0.5 Merchant -3.2 -1.4 -1.8 -4.7 -5.0 1.4 Employee -6.9 -1.6 -2.2 -8.5 -9.0 2.1 Various -4.8 0.0 -0.2 -4.8 -5.0 -2.2 Mean -4.0 0.7 0.5 -3.4 -3.6 -1.5 Sex of head of household Male -3.9 0.7 0.5 -3.2 -3.4 -1.3 Female -4.5 0.7 0.5 —3.8 -4.0 -2.4 Mean -4.0 0.7 0.5 -3.4 -3.6 -l.5 Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. 7.7 Comparison of alternative welfare measures Until this point, the only welfare measures used were the Vartia estimates of equivalent variation (EV) and compensating variation (CV). In implementing the Vartia method, 20 iterations were used to approxi- mate EV and CV. In this section, these measures are compared to both more and less accurate approximations. More accurate approximations can 233 be obtained by increasing the number of iterations used in the Vartia method. Less accurate measures can be calculated using first- and second-order Taylor series approximations of the expenditure function. In addition, consumer surplus is a frequently used measure of welfare impact, in spite of the theoretical problems described in section 3.4.2. Returning to the base scenario, nine measures of welfare impact are calculated for each group of households and presented in Table 7-21. To conserve space, the producer and consumer impact are not listed separately; the figures in the table represent the net impact of the hypothetical devaluation. Three conclusions can be drawn from this table. First, there are consistent differences in the magnitude of the welfare measures. The first-order approximation of compensating variation (CV1) consistently overestimates by about 10% the magnitude of CV as measured by the 50- iteration Vartia estimate (Cvfln. This is because it uses the ”before" quantities as weights in averaging price changes, thus ignoring adapta- tion of consumers to price changes. In contrast, EVl, which uses the "after" quantities as weights, underestimates the most accurate approxi- mation of EV by about 10%. Consumer surplus falls between EVI and CV1, as expected. SeCond, the 20-iteration Vartia estimates and the Second-order Taylor approximations tend to be more accurate (compared to the 50- iteration Vartia estimate) than the first-order Taylor approximation and consumer surplus. And third, the order of different groups of households is virtual- ly the same, no matter which welfare measure is used. In other words, all seven measures show the same relative patterns of welfare impact by location (urban or rural), expenditure quintile, principal occupation, or sex of head of household. The high degree of correlation of different welfare measures across households is dramatically confirmed in Table 7-22. In every ea Table 7-21: Welfare impact of hypd¥hgtical devaluation according to different welfare measures — EV, EV, EV“ EV” cs cvm cv,. cv, cv, Sector Rural -2.8 -3.2 -3.1 -3.1 -3.3 -3.2 -3.2 -3.2 -3.7 Urban -9.8 -10.4 -10.4 -10 5 -11.0 —11.2 -11.3 -11.1 -12.2 Mean -3.2 -3.6 -3.5 -3.5 -3.6 -3.6 -3.6 ~3.6 -4.1 Expenditure quintile lst -2.3 -2.6 -2.5 -2.6 -2.6 -2.6 -2.6 -2.6 -3.0 20 -2.7 -3.0 -2.9 -3.0 -3.1 -3.0 -3.0 -3.0 -3.5 3d -2.3 -Z.7 -2.6 -2.7 -2.8 -2.8 -2.8 -2.7 -3.3 4th —3.4 -3.7 -3.6 -3.7 -3.8 -3.7 -3.8 -3.7 -4.2 5th -5.3 -5.7 -5.7 -5.7 -6.0 -6.0 -6.0 -6.0 -6.6 Mean -3.2 -3.6 -3.5 -3.5 -3.6 -3.6 —3.6 -3.6 -4.1 Principal occupation Farmer -2.2 -2.5 -2.5 -2.5 -2.6 —2.5 -2.6 -2.5 -3.0 Artisan -6.3 -6.8 -6.7 -6.7 -7.0 —7.0 -7.0 -6.9 -7.6 Merchant -4.3 -4.8 -4.8 -4.8 -5.0 -5.1 -5.1 -5.1 -5.7 Employee -8.1 -8.6 -8.6 -8.6 -8.9 -9.1 -9.1 -9.0 -9.8 Various ~4.6 -5.0 -4.9 -5.0 -5.1 -5.1 -5.1 -S.1 -5.7 Mean -3.2 -3.6 -3.5 -3.5 -3.6 -3.6 -3.6 -3.6 -4.1 Sex of head of household Male -3.1 -3.4 -3.4 -3.4 -3.5 -3.5 -3.5 -3.5 -4.0 Female -3.7 -4.0 -4.0 -4.0 -4.1 -4.1 -4.1 -4.1 -4.6 Mean -3.2 -3.6 -3.5 -3.5 -3.6 -3.6 -3.6 -3.6 -4.1 NOTE: EV1 = first-order approximation of equivalent variation EVZ - second-order approximation of equivalent variation EVZO = Vartia estimate of equivalent variation (20 iterations) EVSO c Vartia estimate of equivalent variation (50 iterations) CS I consumer surplus CV50 - Vartia estimate of compensating variation (50 iterations) CV20 = Vartia estimate of compensating variation (20 iterations) CV2 8 second-order approximation of compensating variation CV1 = first-order approximation of compensating variation All figures are expressed as a percentage of expenditure. Source: Simulation based on ENBC data. pair-wise comparison, the correlation coefficient (R2) is over 0.99. This result does not mean that every measure is accurate but rather the ranking of households by impact is very similar across measures. Table 7-23 compares each of the seven rougher approximations of relative welfare impact to the corresponding value of the 50-iteration Vartia estimate. The first line shows the mean difference, or bias, of each measure relative to the reference measure (EV50 or CV50). For qmi'. I. .- " _ Table 7-22: 235 Correlation across households of different welfare measures — EV1 EVz EV20 EVso CS CVso CV20 CV2 CV1 EV1 100.00 99.96 99.92 99.91 99.86 99.71 99.71 99.73 99.54 EV2 99.96 100.00 99.97 99.97 99.95 99.81 99.81 99.82 99.73 EV20 99.92 99.97 100.00 100.00 99.96 99.86 99.86 99.85 99.79 EV50 99.91 99.97 100.00 100.00 99.96 99.86 99.86 99.85 99.79 CS 99.86 99.95 99.96 99.96 100.00 99.95 99.95 99.95 99.91 CV50 99.71 99.81 99.86 99.86 99.95 100.00 100.00 99.99 99.95 CV20 99.71 99.81 99.86 99.86 99.95 100.00 100.00 99.99 99.95 CV2 99.73 99.82 99.85 99.85 99.95 99.99 99.99 100.00 99.93 CV1 99.54 99.73 99.79 99.79 99.91 99.95 99.95 99.93 100.00 Source: Calculated from simulations based on ENBC data. example, EV1 is, on average, half a percentage point (0.51) smaller, in absolute value, than Evflr sponds to a 7.4% error. mate by almost 10%. measure either equivalent variation or compensating variation is smaller (4.6% and 1.6%, respectively). As shown in the second line, this corre- Similarly, CV1 overestimates the Vartia esti- The second-order estimates of CV and EV and the 20-iteration Vartia estimates are even more accurate. four measures have mean biases of less than 1%. The percentage error in using consumer surplus to These I-Lr'r-ur-o .' 236 Table 7-23: Comparison of alternative welfare measures — Comparison with EVso Comparison with CV, EV, EV. EV” CS CS CV” CV, CV, Difference in mean value 0.51 -0.01 0.02 -O.32 0.12 -0.02 0.06- 0.71 Pct difference in mean value -7.38 0.10 -0.27 4.63 -1.63 0.29 -0.79 9.66 Mean absolute r deviation 0.52 0.08 0.02 0.32 0.19 0.02 0.08 0.71 Mean difference in rank 4.42 2.01 0.13 2.05 1.72 0.15 1.49 3.66 Source: Calculated from simulations based on ENBC data. IlIr-«- : A measure may be very inaccurate, yet be unbiased, if the positive and negative errors offset each other. Thus, it is useful to look at the mean absolute value of the error, as shown in the third line of Table 7-23. For example, even though EV2 has a smaller bias than svm” its mean absolute deviation is greater. In other words, EV20 consis- tently provides a slight underestimate, while EV2 is less accurate but has both positive and negative errors. The last line in Table 7-23 shows the mean difference between the order of the household when ranked by different measures. For example, if households are ranked first by EV2 and then by EV30, a household will change only two places, on average, out of the 567 possible rankings. The first—order approximations of welfare impact would be much less accurate, ranking households roughly four places away from their ”true" place, on average. In contrast, the 20-iteration Vartia estimates give virtually the same ranking, household by household, as the SO-iteration Vartia estimates. In summary, for the purpose of ranking household by welfare impact, there is little difference among the alternative welfare measures. However, if the magnitude of the welfare impact is of inte: woulc 7.8 8550 welf the . as g: each than compc impac earne Share There heuse PrOba SECtQ 0f the histoz wa998 demand 0f We? 237 interest, then a second-order approximation or a Vartia approximation would be necessary to reduce the bias to less than 5%. 7-8 W This chapter presents simulations of the relative price changes associated with devaluation and describes their impact on household welfare. Given the structure of the Rwandan economy, it appears that rm; the adverse effect of these changes on urban households is three times 1". as great as the effect on rural households. Furthermore, even within each sector, the higher income households are more adversely affected than the poor. This pattern is due to the sources of income and the M3. slug-a - ,. composition of expenditure. Farmers are relatively insulated from these impacts because of the importance of subsistence production, while wage- earners are the most affected. Furthermore, the poor spend a larger share of their income on staple foods, which tend to be non-tradeables. There is little difference in impact between male- and female-headed households. In the rural areas, price increases of clothing and kerosene probably had the most serious impact on household welfare. In the urban sector, price increases in clothing, transportation, rice and sugar were expected to have the greatest impact. Instead, the higher rates for water and electricity, housing, and beans were the most significant for the average urban household. These results are relatively robust to changes in the assumptions of the model. The conclusions are not significantly affected when historical prices are used rather than hypothetical price, when real wages are assumed to remain constant rather than decline, when alternate demand parameters are used, and when agricultural supply response is assumed to be positive instead of zero. In comparing various welfare measures, the simplest approximations of welfare impact performed relatively well in ranking households by the leve are for ‘ 238 level of impact resulting from price changes. However, these measures are generally biased, with the magnitude of bias being between 8 and 10% for the modeled price changes. CHAPTER EIGHT SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS This chapter reviews the principal results of the study and discusses the implications for policy and for research methods. In addition, a number of limitations of the study are listed and used to make suggestions for extending and improving the approach in future research. 8.1 Summafy of results 8.1.1 Income and expenditure patterns The results of the National Household Budget and Consumption Survey (ENBC) in Rwanda confirm the general view that Rwanda is a predominantly rural, predominantly agricultural, semi-subsistence - economy. Farming is the principal occupation of almost three quarters of Rwandan households. Even in the urban sector, which accounts for 6% of the population, one household in seven relies on agriculture for most of its net income. Subsistence (or non-marketed2vproduction accounts W or“ “W *7" C-e. e. V5.9.” w” for three quarters of the value of food consumption in the rural areas, nAI:E“IE‘€E:E“I§“S3Z§AEEQM3Ewtgta{WSEEEKEEEEEET”HSQen in the cities, home production represents a non-negligible source of food (21% of the value of food consumption, 17% of total expenditure). At the same time, the surVey reveals that there is considerable diversity of income sources in both rural and urban sectors. In the rural sector, 10% of the households obtain most of their income from self-employment in manufacturing and services, the largest sub-sector being the production of traditional beers. Another 15% are primarily occupied as traders, as employees, or in a variety of activities, no one of which accounts for over 50% of total income. In addition, rural households often have three or more income generating activities. Virtually all households brew traditional beer, 40% of them have other 239 240 manufacturing or service activities, a quarter are involved in trading, and half of them earn some form of wage or salary income. Urban households, like their rural counterparts, have diverse sources of income and one-job households are rare. In contrast to the view that the cities are composed primarily of wage-earners, the survey indicates that only 35% of the urban households obtain most of their income from wages and salaries. Over half of the urban household earn most of their income from self-employment. FF— The ENBC results also confirm that urban residents are generally better off than their rural counterparts. Although prices are higher in E the cities, particularly the prices of unprocessed local foods, urban : households have higher levels of expenditure per capita than do rural i households even after taking into account the difference in prices. In the urban sector, the average level of expenditure is 2.4 times that of the rural sector. Furthermore, 87% of the urban household have per capita expenditure levels above the rural median. One surprising result of the ENBC is the absence of a positive relationship between total farm size on the one hand and expenditure and caloric intake on the other. Three reasons for this patterns can be identified. First, small farms tend to be operated by small families due to life cycle patterns. Second, small farms have much higher economic returns per hectare than large farms. Presumably, this results from more intensive cultivation and the fact that, over time, farms have fragmented to smaller sizes in areas where agro-climatic conditions are the best. Third, small farms rely to a larger degree on non-farm sources of income. At the same time, the ENBC data indicate that there is a positive relationship between farm size per adult equivalent and measures of well-being. Not surprisingly, this relationship is stronger among households in which agriculture is the dominant activity. The survey confirms the conventional view that only a small portion of agricultural production is marketed. For all the staple food 241 crops, less than one third of total production reaches the market. In the case of sweet potatoes, bananas, and beans, the proportion is less than 10%. This implies that coffee and other export crops represent a larger percentage of agricultural sales than of agricultural production. In fact, coffee is by far the most important source of cash income among individual crops. Less well recognized, however, is the fact that food crops sales as a whole are twice as important as cash crop sales. Furthermore, most of the food crop sales are destined, not for the urban sector, but for other rural consumers. In other words, in spite of low levels of rural expenditure and the small share of expenditure which is in the form of cash purchases, rural households still account for the bulk of the market demand for food crops in Rwanda. The effect of the price changes associated with devaluation on households is a function of several factors. First, the larger the proportion of total expenditure which is in the form of cash purchases, the more sensitive a household is to any fluctuations in market prices, including devaluation. The ENBC data indicate that market transactions account for 83% of the average urban budget but only 35% of the average rural budget. Furthermore, for the country as a whole and within each sector, market transactions are a larger share of total expenditure (and income) among high-income households than low-income households. The implication is that a price change will affect urban households over twice as much as rural households even in the absence of any difference in the composition of cash expenditure. Similarly, the richest 20% of households would be affected more than twice as much as the poorest 20%. Second, to the extent that devaluation affects food prices, the impact on urban household is unambiguous, but the impact on rural households is less clear. The effect depends, in part, on the direction of change in relative prices and whether a household is a net seller or net buyer of the commodity in question. Analysis of the distribution of rural households by their net sales position in several key food crops H» 242 reveals that, for most crops, about one quarter of the households are net buyers, one quarter net sellers, and half neither buy nor sell. Beans, and to a lesser degree sorghum, present a different pattern in which most rural households are net buyers. Furthermore, supporting the finding of Loveridge (1988), total purchases appear to exceed total sales for beans and sorghum, implying informal imports of these two crops from neighboring countries. The correlation of net sales across commodities is weak and, for a number of commodity pairs, negative. In other words, net buyers of one staple food are not necessarily net buyers of others. At the same time, 45% of rural households are overall net buyers (expressed in caloric terms) of the six major food crops. With regard to the question whether net buyers tend to be poor, the answer is that it depends on the crop. This pattern is most evident in the case of beans, and appears weaker for cassava and sweet potatoes. In the case of white potatoes, net buyers may be better off than net sellers, on average. The third factor influencing the effect of devaluation on households is the percentage of expenditure and of income which can be considered tradeable. Since a successful devaluation raises the price of tradeables relative to non-tradeables, a household gains to the extent that it produces tradeables and consumes non-tradeables. In the rural sector of Rwanda, almost half of all tradeable spending is on clothing, mostly imported cloth and used clothing. In the urban sector, transportation, Clothing, and rice are the most important types of tradeable spending. The tradeable component of cash expenditure is, somewhat surprisingly, the same in rural and urban areas. It varies positively with income in the urban sector but apparently not in the rural sector. On the income side, tradeable production is somewhat erratic, possibly due to measurement and definitional problems. However, among the urban poor, their somewhat lower spending on tradeables is more than offset by very low levels of tradeable output. 243 However, the above measures of welfare impact are incomplete and do not take into account the adaptation of households as consumers and as producers to changing prices. When the demand for a good is highly elastic, the welfare impact of a price increase is less, reflecting the fact that there are substitutes in consumption or that the good is not essential. Similarly, if the supply is price elastic, then a price decrease has a less severe welfare impact, reflecting the fact that there are substitutes in production. The construction of more sophisticated welfare measures depends on estimating a demand model and, for measuring long-term welfare impact, estimating supply response. 8.1.2 Model of consumer demand Separate rural and urban demand models were constructed using seemingly unrelated regression. The functional form used was the Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS) augmented with a squared income term. Prices were included for all food items in the system, but no non-food prices were available. Three household composition variables were included: number of adults, number of children, and sex of head of household. The rural model included 17 food categories, while the urban model contained 21. Each model had nine non-food categories. Food own- price and cross-price elasticities were estimated directly, while non- food price elasticities were derived using Frisch's method which assumes strong separability of preferences. The estimated elasticities of food demand with respect to total expenditure are closely correlated with the cost per calorie of the food product. The least expensive sources of calories (sorghum, cassava, sweet potatoes, bananas, and beans) have the lowest expenditure elasticities in both rural and urban sectors. 'Sweet potatoes have the lowest expenditure elasticity, but are not an inferior good at the mean expenditure level in either sector. More expensive sources of calories such as white potatoes, rice, and banana beer have higher expenditure elasticities. The highest expenditure elasticities are those of factory bee Exp the “10 in 509 dis and tob edu aCrl bei1 ne< 8C0: Btu: bBe: bee: Sha: the res; SO. bein. demdl By 8: Prop: influ 244 beer, animal products, and sugar, all quite costly sources of calories. Expenditure elasticities are generally lower in the urban sector than in the rural sector. For example, white potatoes and banana beer are "luxuries" in the countryside, but they are classified as "necessities" in the cities. Most of the tradeable food items such as rice, bread, sugar, and factory beer are ”luxuries,” implying that they are consumed disproportionately by higher-income households. With regard to non-food categories, housing, household equipment, and transportation are "luxuries" in both urban and rural sectors, while tobacco has the lowest expenditure elasticity. In the case of clothing, education, and health/hygiene, the budget shares are relatively constant across expenditure levels within each sector. The household composition variables reveal that, other things being equal, larger households consume more "luxuries" and fewer "necessities.” This pattern is consistent with the hypothesis of economies of scale in household size, often found in household budget studies. Female-headed households spend significantly less on banana beer in both sectors. In the cities, they also spend less on factory beer, tobacco, and meals away from home, while allocating larger budget shares to vegetables and education. The estimated food price elasticities are roughly proportional to the expenditure elasticities for the same items. In the rural sector, the demand for factory beer, rice, and white potatoes is quite responsive to prices, while that of the staple food commodities is less so. The pattern is less clear in the urban sector, with factory beer being less price-responsive and several staples having price elastic demand, perhaps due to greater substitution possibilities in the cities. By assumption, the derived non-food price elasticities are generally proportional to the corresponding expenditure elasticities. Imposing symmetry of compensated cross-price effects naturally influences the price elasticities more than expenditure elasticities. 245 Nonetheless, the basic conclusions, as discussed above, apply equally to the unrestricted and restricted versions of the model. Quality and measurement error effects were investigated using the within-cluster variation in the variables, as proposed by Deaton (1987 and 1988). Quality effects were tested by analyzing the within-cluster effect of household expenditure on the average price paid for different food items. For no commodity was the quality effect statistically significant, and in a third of the equations, the sign was wrong (negative). Measurement error was tested by examining the within- cluster effect of prices on budget shares. Of the 37 rural and urban food equations, only three showed any sign of significant measurement error effects. 8.1.3 Impact of price changes associated with devaluation In the base scenario, the price of each budget category is assumed to rise in proportion with the tradeable content of the category. Wages are assumed to fall by 4-8%, in accordance with the historical patterns of other devaluation episodes, as analyzed by Edwards (1989). Demand response is simulated using the parameters from the restricted model (with symmetry imposed). Although supply response is not included in the base scenario, the effect of price changes on income and the consequent effect of income on demand (the profit effect) is simulated. The welfare impaCt, in the form of equivalent variation and compensating variation, is measured using Vartia's method with 50 iterations. In order to make full use of the sample data, the demand response, profit effect, and the welfare and nutritional impact are simulated for each household in the sample and then aggregated to the appropriate group. The most striking result of the simulation under the base scenario is that the negative welfare impact (expressed as a percentage of total expenditure) is over three times greater for urban households than for rural households. The price changes associated with devaluation are 246 equivalent to a 3% reduction in the real income of rural households and a 10% drop in real income for urban households. In addition, it is twice as great for the richest 20% of households as it is for the poorest 20%. Households whose primary occupation is farming are least affected, while wage earners are the most severely affected. Female- headed households are slightly more affected than male-headed households. Caloric intake rises slightly, presumably because the (nontradeable) staple foods have become less expensive relative to many (tradeable) non-food items. Within the rural sector, households which are poor, agricultural, male-headed and/or in the Eastern region are more insulated from the devaluation than others. In the urban sector, households which are poor, agricultural, female-headed, and/or in cities other than Kigali are least affected. This confirms the conventional wisdom that the urban poor are harder hit than the rural poor, but it is at odds with the common perception that low-income urban households are affected more than higher-income households in the city. Historical prices were examined for the two years before and the seven months after the Rwandan franc was devalued on November 20, 1990. An index of consumer prices based on 35 goods showed that prices rose sharply during October 1990. This rise is probably the result of the outbreak of guerilla warfare during that month. Developing separate indexes for tradeable and non-tradeable goods shows that both rose in parallel fashion in October, but in November tradeable good prices continued rising while non-tradeable prices fell. The real exchange rate, defined as the ratio of tradeable to nontradeable prices, rose 31% from one month before to seven months after the devaluation. The average prices during the second quarter of 1990 were used to simulate the ”before" situation, while those of the second quarter of 1991 were used to represent the "after" situation. Although the individual price changes bore little resemblance to the hypothesized 247 price changes, the welfare impact was similar in the two cases. Historical prices affected rural, poor, and agricultural households the least, while the effect on urban, high-income, and wage-earning households was the greatest. These results are relatively robust to changes in the assumptions of the model. The relative impact on different types of households is no different in any meaningful way when 1) real wages are assumed to remain constant rather than decline, 2) agricultural supply response is introduced, and 3) alterative demand parameters are adopted. A comparison of alternative measures of welfare impact revealed that the simplest first-order approximations performed relatively well in ranking household by impact. On the other hand, these measures are generally biased by 8-10%. For example, the first-order approximation of compensating variation overstates the welfare impact of price changes. 8.2 Implications for policy Several policy implications can be drawn from the results of this study. Some apply to Rwanda alone, while others may be applicable to other less developed countries with similar economies. .8.2.l Magnitude of the impact of devaluation In Rwanda, and by extension in similar semi-subsistence agricultural economies, the expenditure-switching effect of devaluation has a relatively moderate impact on rural households and the poor in general. In all the scenarios considered, the effect on the poor was equivalent to a reduction in real income of 4% or less. The impact on caloric intake is even less, perhaps slightly positive. In one sense, this may represent an overstatement of the impact, since the model does account for substitution within each budget category. For example, the effect of higher prices for petroleum products may induce substitution 248 within energy expenditures, but these cannot be captured in a model which does not disaggregate energy spending. On the other hand, these results apply only to the relative price (or ”expenditure switching”) effects of devaluation. The simulation does not incorporate any change in aggregate output (”expenditure- reducing"). In particular, the short-term contractionary effect, identified in some devaluation episodes, could result in unemployment. Nor does it take into account other aspects of the structural adjustment program such as reductions in government expenditure, restrained growth of public sector employment, trade liberalization, and so on. The results of the simulations are consistent with political explanations of resistance to currency devaluation. It is sometimes argued that policy makers are reluctant to devalue the currency because of a direct stake they have in access to ”cheap" foreign exchange. Only weak support was found for the idea that higher-income households consume more tradeables, whose relative price rises with devaluation. However, the simulation indicates that rural farmers, who represent 73% of Rwandan households, experience price changes equivalent to a small (2.4%) reduction in real income, but urban wage-earners, who account for less than 2% of all households, face price changes which are equivalent to a 12% reduction in real income. 8.2.2 Alleviation of the impact of devaluation With respect to the rural sector, there are no simple ways to alleviate the impact of devaluation on rural households. The same factor that protects them from the devaluation, limited participation in the market economy, also insulates them from the benefits of price policies. Manipulation of food prices, even if it were practical, would leave many rural households unaffected and have mixed effects on the remainder. One exception is bean prices, reduction of which would benefit Over 70% of the rural households. Furthermore, because net purchases rep hou The dis tha‘. neg; fea: imp< bent C101 the C051 249 represent a larger share of the expenditure of the poor than other households, lower bean prices would benefit the poor disproportionately. These results confirm the wisdom of the government's decision to discontinue efforts to support bean prices. They also suggest that restrictions on bean imports would, by raising prices, be particularly harmful to the poor. Furthermore, it suggests that efforts to remove impediments to ”informal” regional trade would yield significant benefits for poor rural households. To the extent that the informal trade is subject to additional costs because it is not officially recognized, legalization of this trade could well reduce marketing costs. In addition, hypothetical and the historical simulation indicated that increased prices for clothing account for a large portion of the negative impact on rural households. Actual subsidies may not be feasible, given budget constraints, but reduction or elimination of import duties on clothing could be considered. In order to target the benefits toward the poor, the tax reduction could be restricted to used clothing, which is purchased disproportionately by the poor. Although the effect of agricultural price policy is constrained by the limited market participation of most rural households, the impact of cost-reducing agricultural technology is much deeper and more widely distributed. For example, an increase in the price of sweet potatoes benefits roughly a quarter of the rural households, with a small number of households capturing much of the gains. By contrast, a reduction in the cost of producing sweet potatoes benefits over 85% of the rural households. Furthermore, for a given change in cost/price, the benefits of cost-reducing technology are much greater because they apply to the volume of production rather than the small portion which is marketed. The scope for assisting the urban poor is greater, since cash purchases are an important part of expenditure (68% for the poorest 20% Of the urban households). In the early stages of the structural 250 adjustment program, the government of Rwanda gave special access to foreign exchange for the importation of sugar, cooking oil, and wheat flour. Since these are the food items with the highest expenditure elasticities in the urban areas, the benefits of such a policy accrue disproportionately to higher-income urban residentsl. Subsidies on an inferior good would be self-targeting in the sense that the absolute benefits of subsidies would be greater for the poor than other households. But the ENBC data indicate that there are no inferior goods at the mean level of expenditure in the urban sector. Nonetheless, a subsidy on sweet potatoes would be more targeted than any other food subsidy: the absolute benefit would be relatively constant across households, but it would represent a larger share of the budget of poor households. 8.3 Implications for research methods 8.3.1 Advantages of micgo-simglation In order to make full use of the sample data, the demand response, profit effect, and the welfare and nutritional impact are simulated for each household in the sample and then aggregated to the appropriate group. This ”micro-simulation" approach is in contrast to the usual practice of simulating the impact of price change on a small number of "representative" or "archetypal" households. Micro-simulation allows the analyst to examine the impact on any sub-group of the population, rather than being limited to the selected ”representative" households. For example, it allows the results to be disaggregated by expenditure quintile, by region, by sex of head of household, or any other classification. In addition, this approach provides some information about the variation within each group. For example, it was shown that the five l. The expenditure elasticities of these items range from 0.97 to 1.42. Thus, the benefits as a percentage of expenditure are constant or increasing as a function of household expenditure. 251 occupational groups explain about one half of the variation in welfare impact across households. Combined with household expenditure, sex of head of household, and urban/rural residence, 65% of the variation is explained. This type of information is not available when the simulation is run for a small number of ”representative" households. A third advantage of micro-simulation is that it allows the use of a demand specification without the property of exact aggregation. The Almost Ideal Demand System, which does allow exact aggregation, was shown to be insufficiently flexible in representing the relationship between budget share and total expenditure. Yet adding a quadratic expenditure term is not an option unless micro-simulation is used because the resulting functional form does not have exact aggregation. Naturally, the cost of micro-simulation is that it is computationally more burdensome. The additional programming time is not that significant since it only involves iterating the same procedure for each household in the sample. And the additional computational time becomes less important with each advance in micro-computer technology. 8.3.2 Factors affeCting the impact of devaluation Various approaches have been used to analyze the distributional impact of devaluation. Cross-country econometric studies tend to focus on wage rates, since time-series data are available for a number of countries (e.g. Edwards, 1989). For countries like Rwanda, wage rates are a highly deceptive measure of the welfare of the poor. As noted above, only 6% of the households in Rwanda obtain most of their income from wages. Furthermore, these households are disproportionately located in the urban sector. Even within the urban sector, employees have income levels significantly above the mean. The other approach is to examine the average composition of spending and income (e.g. Sahn, 1990 and Glewwe and de Tray, 1988 and 1989). This is the core of the method used in this study, but several caveats must be mentioned. First, as mentioned above, the use of (I) m bx 3L Va Si us 252 averages hides a large amount of variation within the population. Second, it is not always clear whether cash budgets or total expenditure are being analyzed. This study indicates that the importance of home production in the budget may be at least as important as the tradeable component of the budget in determining the effect of price changes, including those associated with devaluation. 8.3.3 W The conclusions with regard to alternative welfare measures is mixed. The simplest welfare measure is the first-order approximation of compensating variation. This measure uses only the ”before" budget and income shares, thus avoiding completely the need to estimate demand. This measure is highly correlated with the most sophisticated welfare measures and performs quite well in ranking households by welfare impact. If the only objective of a study is to determine which groups are most benefited or least hurt, then this is a very cost-effective approach. The reason for this is that demand response is a second-order effect, while the budget shares are first order effects. In geometric terms, the budget shares are the rectangle portion of the trapezoid, while the demand response determines the size of the triangle at the end of the trapezoid. In the same fashion, the income shares are first- order effects while the supply response is a second-order effect. In other words, a respectable approximation of the ”profit effect" can be obtained without estimating supply response. This is fortunate, because budget and income shares are much more widely available than demand and supply response parameters. On the other hand, the first-order approximation of compensating variation overestimates the "true" welfare impact. In the base simulation of this study, the magnitude of the overestimate was 8-10%. If price and income elasticities are to be estimated, then it is worth using the Vartia method to estimate willingness-to-pay. As Deaton If?!“ 253 argues, willingness to pay requires no information beyond what is needed to calculate consumer surplus, yet it is conceptually superior to consumer surplus. Furthermore, the intuitive meaning of willingness to pay is arguably easier to explain to the non-specialist reader than is the meaning of consumer surplus. Equivalent variation (EV) appears to be better suited to applied policy analysis than compensating variation, in spite of the popularity of the latter. The principal advantage is the ability of EV to rank alternative policy outcomes. 8.4 mi ation t e stud u e t s fo u u e research Perhaps the greatest weakness of this study is the use of exogenous price changes to simulate devaluation. This study made use of- price trends observed in other countries after currency devaluation. Nonetheless, a number of somewhat arbitrary judgements had to be made in classifying tradeable and nontradeable goods, most notably in the case of beans and factory beer. The most serious implication of this approach is that there is no mechanism to equilibrate supply and demand. One alternative would be to set the new price of tradeable goods exogenously, since by definition their price is set by the international market, and allow non-tradeable prices to be set endogenously such that supply and demand are equatedl. Although it is not at all clear that such a method would be more successful in predicting price changes, it would have the advantage of being internally consistent. A related problem is that prices were assumed to change by the same percentage throughout the country. However, devaluation usually involves sharp increases in transportation costs. To the extent that transportation costs rise more than the price of a given commodity, the 1. This approach was attempted in the present study, but the lack of exact aggregation in the demand specification meant that it was difficult to reliably predict the direction of price change necessary to reduce the gap between supply and demand. As a result, the system tended to "explode" after seven or eight iterations. 254 percentage increase in price will be lower where it is produced than elsewhere. The magnitude of this difference depends on 1) the share of transportation costs in the final consumer price and 2) how much higher transportation costs rose relative to the commodity. Following this logic, the geographic variation in the percentage price increase should be greatest for nontradeable goods with a low value/bulk ratio, such as cassava and sweet potatoes. The incorporation of this effect, such as with a spatial equilibrium model, would be more important in a large country with a poor road network. A third limitation of the study is the use of strong separability assumptions to derive non-food price elasticities. Although this method produced highly plausible elasticities, it would have been preferable to estimate non-food price elasticities directly. This, however, would require a much larger data base which would permit the construction of price indexes for each non-food category. Nonetheless, the analysis in section 7.6 demonstrates that the basic results of this study are not very sensitive to changes in the demand parameters. One more weakness of the study is that only seven months of prices after devaluation were available for the analysis. If the devaluation is ultimately unsuccessful in addressing the external imbalance, then the devaluation may well have been insufficient. In this case, the relatively weak welfare impact (at least for rural households) may be attributed to the overly modest exchange rate adjustment. This study confined its attention to the expenditure-switching effects of devaluation. The research approach used could be extended to incorporate the impact of change in employment or the impact of other aspects of the structural adjustment program. The only constraint on the application of this method to other policy changes is that the policies must be able to be translated into price and income changes. Thus, the doubling of oil prices or alternative taxes on factory beer 255 could be modeled more easily than the impact of reductions in public health spending. Finally, as was mentioned earlier, the distributional impact of devaluation is highly dependent on the structure of the economy. Nonetheless, many aspects of the structure of the Rwandan economy are similar to those in other semi-subsistence agricultural economies. This study has demonstrated the feasibility of calculating "exact" measures of welfare impact in the context of micro-simulation. However, the generalizability of these results to other countries cannot be determined until similar studies are carried out elsewhere. “1--.-. r..- .Kj LIST 01“ REFERENCES LIST OF REFERENCES Addison, T. and L. Demery. (1990). "Adjustment and income distribution: Some methodological issues." in Pinstrup-Anderson, P. (ed.) Macroeconomic Policy ReforerPovertyLvend Nutrition: Analytical Methodologiee. Food and Nutrition Program Monograph 3. Cornell University, Ithaca, New York. Alderman, H. (1986). The Effect of Food Price and Income Changee on the Acguieition of Food byeLow-income Houeeholde. International Food Policy Research Institute. Washington, D.C. Alexander, 8.5. (1952). "Effects of a devaluation on a trade balance." Internationel Monepery Fund Steff Papers 2: 263-278. Allen, R. and A. Bowley. (1935). Family Expenditure. P.S. King and Son, London. Ansoanuur, J. (1991). "Price elasticity of supply and expenditure elasticities of demand of principal agricultural commodities in Rwanda." Report No. 159. Rwandan Agricultural Surveys and Policy Analysis Project. U.S. Agency for International Development. Kigali, Rwanda. Askari, H. and J. Cummings. (1976). Agricultural Supply Responses: A Survey of Econometric Evidence. Praeger. New York, New York. Barnum, H.N. and L. Squire. (1979). A Model of en Agricultural Houeehold: Theory end Evidence. Occasional Paper No. 27. World Bank. Washington, D.C. Becker, G. (1965). "A theory of the allocation of time." Economic Journal 75 (299): 493-517. Blackorby, C., D. Donaldson, and D. Maloney. (1984). "Consumer's surplus and welfare change in a simple dynamic model." Review of Economic Studies 51: 171—6. Blejer, M.I. and I. Guerrero. (1988). "Stabilization policies and income distribution in the Philippines." Finance and Development 25 (December): 6-8. Brown, J. et a1. (1978). Multi-purpose household surveys in developing countries. Proceedings of the Study Session organized by the OECD Development Centre, 14-18 November, 1977, Paris. Chayanov, A. (1966). The Theory of the Peasant Economy. Richard D. Irwin Inc., Homewood, Illinois. Connolly, M. and D. Taylor. (1976). "Testing the monetary approach to devaluation in developing countries." Journal of Political Economy 84 (4): 849-859. Cooper, R. (1971). Exchange rate devaluation in developing countriee. Princeton Essays on International Finance No. 86. Princeton, N.J. 256 257 Cornia, G., R. Jolly, and R. Jolly. (eds.). (1987). Adjustment with a Humen Face: Protecting the Vulnerablegend Promoting Growth. Clarendon Press. Oxford, U.K. de Borger, B. (1989). "Estimating the welfare implications of in—kind government programs, A general numerical approach." Journal of Public Economics 38: 215-226. de Janvry, A., A. Fargeix, and E. Sadoulet. (1988). "The welfare effects of stabilization policies and structural adjustment programs analyzed in CGE frameworks: Results and agenda." Working Paper No. 460. Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics. University of California. Berkeley, California. de Janvry, A., A. Fargeix, and E. Sadoulet. (1990). "The welfare effects of stabilization policies and structural adjustment programs analyzed in computable general equilibrium framework." in Pinstrup-Anderson, P. (ed.) Mecroeconomic Policy Reform, Povertyeeand Nutrition: Anelytical Methodologiee. Food and Nutrition Program Monograph 3. Cornell University, Ithaca, New York. Deaton, A. (1974). "A reconsideration of the empirical implications of additive preferences." The Economic Journal 84 (334): 338-348. Deaton, A. (1980). "The measurement of welfare: Theory and practical guidelines." Working Paper No. 7. Living Standards Measurement Study. World Bank. Washington, D.C. Deaton, A. (1987a). "Estimation of own and cross price elasticities from household survey data." Journal of Econometrice 36: 7-30. Deaton, A. (1987b). "Econometric issues for tax design for developing countries." in Newberry, D. and N. Stern (eds.). The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countriee. Oxford University Press. New York, New York. Deaton, A. (1988). "Quality, quantity, and spatial variation in price." Americen Economic Review 78: 418-30. Deaton, A. (1989). "Household survey data and pricing policies in developing countries." World Bank Economic Revieg 3 (2): 183-210. Deaton, A. and A. Brown. (1972). "Surveys in applied economics: Models of consumer behavior." Economic Journal 82 (328): 1145-1236. Deaton, A. and A. Case. (1987). Analysis of Household Expenditure. Working Paper No. 28. Living Standards Measurement Study. World Bank. Washington, D.C. Deaton, A. and M. Irish. (1984). "Statistical models for zero expenditure in household budgets." Journel of Public Economics 23: 59- 80. " Deaton, A. and J. Muelbauer. (1980a). Economics and Consumer Beheyior. Cambridge University Press. Cambridge, U.K. Deaton, A. and J. Muelbauer. (1980b). "An almost ideal demand system." American Economic Review 70: 312-326. Demery, L. and T. Addison. (1987). The Allevietion of Poverty under Structurel Adjustment. World Bank. Washington, D.C. 258 Dervis, K, J. de Melo, and S. Robinson. (1982). General Eguilibrium Models for Development Policy. Cambridge University Press. Cambridge, U.K. Diaz Alejandro, C.F. (1963). "A note on the impact of devaluation and the redistributive effect." The Journal of Political Economy 71 (6): 577-580. Dioné, J. (1989). Informing Food Security Policy,in Mali: Interactione between Technology. Institutions, and Market Reforme. Ph.D. dissertation. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan. Donovan, D.J. (1981). "Real responses associated with exchange rate action in selected upper credit tranche stabilization programs." IMF Staff Papers 28: 698-727. Dumagen, J. and C. Mount. (1989). "Measuring Hicksian welfare change from Marshallian demand functions." Working Paper No. 91-10. Department of Agricultural Economics. Cornell University. Ithaca, New York. Edwards, S. (1986). "Are devaluations contractionary?" Review of Economics and Statietice 68 (3): 501-508. Edwards, S. (1989). Real Exchange Rates, Develuation, and Adjustment: Exchange Rate Policy in Developing Countriee. MIT Press. Cambridge, Massachusetts. Fomby, T., R. Hill, and S. Johnson. (1984). Advanced Econometric Methods. Springer-Verlag. New York, New York. Frenkel, J. and H. Johnson. (eds.) (1976). The Monetery Approach to the Balance of Paymente. University of Toronto Press. Toronto. Frisch, R. (1959). "A complete scheme for computing all direct and cross demand elasticities in a model of many sectors." Econometrica 27: 177- 196. Glewwe, P. and D. de Tray. (1989). The Poor in Latin Americe during Ad- justment: A Case Study of Peru. Working Paper No. 56. Living Standards Measurement Study. World Bank. Washington, D.C. Glewwe, P. and D. de Tray. (1988). The Poor duringeAdjustment: A Case Study of Cote d’Ivoire. Working Paper No. 47. Living Standards Measurement Study. World Bank. Washington, D.C. Godfrey, M. (1985). "Trade and exchange rate policy in sub-Saharan Africa." IDS Bulletin 16 (3): 31-38. Goetz, S. (1990). Market Reforms, Food Securitykpend theepaeheCrop-Food Crop Debate in Southeaetern Senegal. Ph.D. dissertation. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan. Gray, C. (1982). Food Coneumption Parameters for Brazil and their Applicetion to Food Policy. Research Report No. 12. International Food Policy Research Institute. Washington, D.C. Green, R. and J. Alston. (1990). "Elasticities in AIDS models." American Journal of Agricultural Economice 72 (2): 442-445. 259 Haggblade, S. with assistance from N. Minot. (1987). "Opportunities for enhancing performace in Rwanda's alcoholic beverage subsector." PRIME Working Paper. U.S. Agency for International Development. Kigali, Rwanda. Hausman, J. (1981). "Exact consumer’s surplus and deadweight loss." Americen Economic Review 71: 662-676. Heien, D. and C. Wessells. (1990). "Demand system estimation with micro- data: A censored regression approach." Journal of Bueinessgend Economic Statistics 8 (3): 365-371. Heller, P. et a1. (1988). Implicationeeof Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs for Poverty: Experiencee in Selected Countriee. IMF Occasional No. 58. Washington, D.C. Helms, J. (1985). "Expected consumer's surplus and the welfare effects of price stabilization." Internationel Economic Review 26: 603-17. Henderson, A. (1940). "Consumer's surplus and the compensating variation." Review of Economic Studiee 8: 117-21. Heremans, R. (1988). Introductionge l'Hietoireedu Rwenda. Editions Rwandaise. Kigali, Rwanda. Hicks, J. (1940). "The rehabilitation of consumer surplus." Review of Economic Studiee 8: 108-15. Hymer, S. and S. Resnick. (1969). "A model of an agrarian economy with nonagricultural activities." Amerigen Economic Review 59 (4): 493-506. Iqbal, F. (1986). "The demand and supply of funds among agricultural households in India." in Singh, I., L. Squire, and J. Strauss. (eds.). Agricultural Household Models: Extensions, Applicatigpe, and Policy. Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore, Maryland. Jeon, B. and G. von Furstenberg. (1986). "Techniques for measuring the welfare effects of protection: Appraising the choices." Journel of Policy Modeling 8 (2): 273-303. Johansson, P. (1987). The Economic Theory and Measurement of Environmental Benefite. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K. Johnson, 0. and J. Salope. (1980). "Distributional aspects of stabilization programs in developing countries." Internetional Monetary Fund Steff Papere 27 (1): 1-23. Judge, et al. (1988). Introduction to the Theory and Practice of Econometrice. John Wiley and Company. New York, New York. Kamin, S. (1988). "Devaluation, external balance, and macroeconomic performance: A look at the numbers." Princeton Studies in International Finance. No. 62. Princeton, New Jersey. King, R.P. and D. Byerlee. (1977). Income Dietribution, Coneumption Patterns, and Coneumption Linkages in Rural Sierra Leone. African Rural Economy Paper No. 16. Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan. Krugman, P. and L. Taylor. (1978). "Contractionary effects of devaluation." Journal of International Economige 8: 445-456. 260 Laraki, K. (1988). Food Consumptioneend Food Subsidiee in Morocco: Justificationeefor Policy Reform. Ph.D. dissertation. Department of Agricultural Economics. Cornell University. Ithaca, New York. Lau, L., W. Lin, and P. Yotopoulos. (1978). "The linear logarithmic expenditure system: An application to consumption-leisure choice." Econometrica 46 (4): 843-68. Leurquin, P. (1963). Le Niveau de Vie dee,Populetion§,Rurale§ du Rwanda- Urundi. Université Lovanium de Leopoldville. Brussels. Liedholm, C. and D. Mead. (1987). Small Scale Industriee in Developing Countries: Empirical Evidence:end Policy Implicetions. International Development Paper No. 9. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State University. East Lansing, Michigan. Lluch, C., A. Powell, and R. Williams. (1977). Patterns in Household De- mand end Savinge. Oxford University Press. Oxford, U.K. Loveridge, S. (1989). Usee ofpgerm and Market Sugyey Deta to Inform Food Security Policy in Rwande. Ph.D. dissertation. Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University. East Lansing, Michigan. Low, A. (1986). Agriculturel Development in Southern Africe: Ferm- Houeehold Economics and the Food Crisis. Heinemann, Portsmouth, New Hampshire. McDonald, J. and R. Moffit. (1980). "The uses of Tobit analysis." Review of Economice,and Statistice 62: 318-321. McKenzie, G.W. (1983). Measuring Economic Welfage. Cambridge University Press. Cambridge, U.K. McKenzie, G. and I. Pearce (1982). "Welfare measurement - A synthesis." Americen Economic Review 72: 669-682. Miles, M.A. (1979). "The effects of devaluation on the trade balance and the balance of payments: Some new results." Journal of Political Economy 87 (3): 600-620. Ministere de l’Agriculture. (1987). Résultats de l'Enguéte Nationale Agricole 1984. Volume 1. Kigali, Rwanda. Ministere des Finances et de l'Economie. (1987). L'Economie Rwandaise: 25 Ans d'Effort. Direction Générale de la Politique Economique. Kigali, Rwanda. Ministere du Plan. (1988). Consommation et Sourceepde Revenu des Ménages Ruraux. Volume 3 of the National Household Budget and Consumption Survey (ENBC). Direction Générale de la Statistique. Kigali, Rwanda. Ministere du Plan. (1991). Consommation et Sources de Revenu des Ménages Urbains. Volume U3 of the National Household Budget and Consumption Survey (ENBC). Direction Générale de la Statistique. Kigali, Rwanda. Ministere du Plan. (1988). Presentetion Methodologigue de l'Echentillon et de leegollecte en Milieu Urbain. Volume Ul of the National Household Budget and Consumption Survey. Direction Générale de la Statistique. Kigali, Rwanda. 261 Ministere du Plan. (1986). Préeentetion Methodologigue de l'Echentillon et de la Collecte en Miliep Rural. Volume 1 of the National Household Budget and Consumption Survey. Direction Générale de la Statistique. Kigali, Rwanda. Ministere du Plan. (1991). Indices Nationel dee Prix a la Coneommetion. Bulletin No. 001. Direction Générale de la Statistique. Kigali, Rwanda. Mudbhary, P. (1988). A Demand Syetem Analysis of Food Consumption in Nepal. Ph.D. dissertation. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michi- gan State University. East Lansing, Michigan. Newberry, D. (1987). "Identifying desirable directions of agricultural price reform in Korea." in Newberry, D. and N. Stern (eds.). The Theory of Taxation for DevelopingeCountries. Oxford University Press. New York, New York. Ngirabatware, A., L. Murembya, and D. Mead. (1988). "Medium and large private manufacturing firms in Rwanda: Diagnostic study of current situation and policy impact." Working Paper No. 9. Policy Reform Initiatives in Manufacturing and Employment Project. U.S. Agency for International Development. Kigali, Rwanda. Ngirumwami, Jean Léonard. (1989). "Résultats de l'Enquéte Commerce Frontalier au Rwanda." Direction des Statistiques Agricoles, Ministere de l'Agriculture. Kigali, Rwanda. Niehans, J. (1984). Internationel Economic Theory. Columbia University Press. New York, New York. Pakpahan, A. (1988). Food Demand Analysis in Urben Weet Jaye, Indonesia. Ph.D. dissertation. Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University. East Lansing, Michigan. Phlip, L. (1983). Applied Consumption Analysie. North-Holland, Amsterdam. Pitt, M. (1983). "Food preferences and nutrition in rural Bangladesh." The Review of Economics and Statistics 65 (1): 105-114. Pitt, M. and M. Rosenweig. (1986). "Agricultural prices, food consumption, and the health and productivity of Indonesian farmers." in Singh, I., L. Squire, and J. Strauss. (eds.). Agriculturel Household Modele: Extensions, Applicationej and Policy. Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore, Maryland. Prais, S. and H. Houtaker. (1955). The Anelysis of Family Budgete. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Pudney, S. (1989). Modelling Individual Choice: TheeEconometrice_of Cornere, Kinks, and Holes. Basil Blackwell. Oxford, U.K. Republique Rwandaise. (1990a). "Memorandum sur la Politique Economique et Financiére du Rwanda pour le Premier Programme Annuel (Octobre 1990 - Septembre 1991)." Kigali, Rwanda. Republique Rwandaise. (1990b). "Document Cadre de Politique Economique et Financiére a Moyen Terme (Octobre 1990 - Septembre 1993)." Kigali, Rwanda. 262 Roe, T. and T. Graham-Tomasi. (1986). "Yield risk in a dynamic model of the agricultural households." in Singh, I., L. Squire, and J. Strauss. (eds.). Agricultural Household Models: ExtensionsLiApplications, and Policy. Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore, Maryland. Sahn, D. (1990). "Poverty, food security, and policy reform in Africa." in Pinstrup-Anderson, P. (ed.) Macroeconomic Policy Reform, Poverty, egg Nutrition: Analytical Methodologiee. Food and Nutrition Program Monograph 3. Cornell University, Ithaca, New York. Sahn, D. and A. Sarris. (1991). ”Structural adjustment and the welfare of rural smallholders: A comparative analysis from sub-Saharan Africa." World Bank Economic Review 5 (2): 259-289. Samuelson, P. (1942). "Constancy of the marginal utility of income." in Lange, O., et a1. Studies in Methematical Economics and Econometrice. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, Illinois. Schafer, H. (1989). Real exchange rates and economic performance. Ph.D. dissertation. Dept. of Economics and Business. North Carolina State University. Raleigh, North Carolina. Schmidt, P. (1976). gconometrige. Marcel-Dekker Inc. New York, New York. Scott, C. (1985). "Systeme de pondération pour l’Enquéte Nationale sur le Budget et la Consommation des Ménages." Trip report. Kigali. Scott, G. (1988). Potatoes in Central Africa: A Study of Burundi, Rwanda, end Zaire. International Potato Center, Lima. Singh, I., L. Squire, and J. Strauss. (eds.) (1986). Agricultural Houeehold Models: Extensions, Applications, and Policy. Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore, Maryland. Sirven, P. J. Gotanegre, and C. Prioul. (1974). Géogrephie du Rwanda. Editions A. de Boeck. Brussels. Smith, V. and J. Strauss. (1986). "Simulating the rural economy in a subsistence environment: Sierra Leone." in Singh, I., L. Squire, and J. Strauss. (eds.). Agricultural Household Models: Extensioney Applicetiope. and Policy. Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore, Maryland. Stone, J. (1954). "Linear expenditure systems and demand analysis: An application to the pattern of British demand." Economic Journal 64: 511- 527. Strauss, J. (1983). Socio-Economic Determinants of Food Consumption and Production in Rural Sierre_Leone: Application of an Agricultural Household Model with Severel Commoditiee. International Development Paper No. 5. Department of Agricultural Economics. Michigan State University. East Lansing, Michigan. Swamy, F. and H.P. Binswanger. (1983). "Flexible consumer demand systems and linear estimation: Food in India." Americen Journal of Agricultural Economics 65 (4): 675-684. Thomas, D., J. Strauss, and M. Barbosa. (1989). "Estimating the impact of income and price changes on consumption in Brazil." Discussion Paper No. 589. Economic Growth Center. Yale University, New Haven, Connecticut. 263 Timmer, P. And H. Alderman. (1979). "Estimating consumption parameters for food policy analysis." American Journal of Agriculture; Economice 61. Tobin. J. (1958). "Estimation of relationships for limited dependent variables." Econometrica 26: 24-36. Tsiang, S.C. (1961). "The role of money in trade-balance stability: Synthesis of the elasticity and absorption approaches." American Economic Review 51 (5): 912-936. Tweeten, L. (1989). Farm PolicyeAnalyeie. Westview Press. Boulder, Colorado. Varian, H. (1984). Microeconomic Analysis. W.W. Norton and Company, New York, New York. Vartia, Y. (1983). "Efficient methods of measuring welfare change and compensated income in terms of ordinary demand functions." Econometrica 51 (1): 79-98. Weber, M. et a1. (1988). "Informing food security decisions in Africa: Empirical Analysis and policy dialogue." Americen Journal of Agricultural Economice 70 (5): 1044-1054. World Bank. (1985). Rwanda — The Manufacturing Sector: Performance and Policy Issuee. Washington, D.C. World Bank. (1984). World Development Report 1984. World Bank, Washington, D.C. World Bank. (1990a). World Development Report 1990. World Bank. Washington, D.C. World Bank. (1990b). Making Adjustment Work for the Poor: A Fremework for Policy Reform in Africe. World Bank. Washington, D.C. World Bank. (1991). Rwanda - Agriculturel Strategy Review. Washington, D.C. World Bank/United Nations Development Program. (1989). Africa’s Adjustment and Growth in the 1980e. World Bank. Washington, D.C. Zellner, A. (1962). "An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias." Journal of the American Statisticel Aseociation 57: 348-368. Zulu, J. and S. Nsouli. (1985). Adjustment Programe in Africa: The Recent Experience. Occasional Paper No. 34. International Monetary Fund. Washington, D.C. APPENDICES APPENDIX A DEVALUATION AND BEAN PRICES APPENDIX A DEVALUATION AND BEAN PRICES We expect devaluation to raise the price of beans less than the increase in the local price of devaluation for two reasons. First, if the international supply of beans is perfectly elastic, then the price of beans will increase in the same proportion as the parallel exchange rate, since beans are imported unofficially. Most studies (e.g. Edwards, 1989) show that the parallel market premium declines following devaluation. This implies that the cost of foreign exchange on the parallel market rises less than the cost of foreign exchange in the official market. Second, the increase in the price of beans will be less than the increase in the parallel exchange rate if the regional supply of beans are not perfectly elastic. It is probably more realistic to assume that Rwandan demand is "large" relative to the regionally traded volumes of beans so that the supply of imported beans is not perfectly elastic. In this case, the price increase will be dampened in proportion to the price elasticity of market demand for beans in Rwanda. The market demand for beans is likely to be highly price-responsive because the market is "thin" in the sense that only a small portion (16% according to the ENBC) of the total demand for beans is in the form of market purchases. If the elasticity of demand for beans is somewhat around 0.8 (see Chapter 6), then the elasticity of market demand will be almost 5.0 (0.8/0.16 = 4.8). Thus, a 5% reduction in the volume of imported beans would be necessary to raise the domestic price by 1%. In summary, the increase in the price of Rwandan beans is likely to be less than the increase in the price of foreign currency in the official market. This is because 1) devaluation tends to raise the 264 265 parallel market rate less than the official rate and 2) if the regional supplies of beans are not perfectly elastic, then bean prices will rise proportionately less than the parallel exchange rate, particularly given the thinness of the bean market in Rwanda. At the same time, it should be recognized that any increase in the price of beans reduces the real income of perhaps 70% of rural households. Furthermore, such a price increase is likely to have a regressive impact even within the rural sector, reducing the real income of low-income households more than that of other households (see Table 5"21). APPENDIX B ADULT EQUIVALENCE SCALES 266 APPENDIX B ADULT EQUIVALENCE SCALES Adult equivalence scales are used to measure the "size" of a household in terms of consumption requirements. The simplest approach to calculating adult equivalence scales is to define them in terms of the caloric requirements of household members. Although calorie-based equivalence scales do not take into account non-food consumption needs, this is a less serious bias in a country like Rwanda in which food represents a large share of the value of total expenditure. The equivalence scales used in this study are presented below. Table B-1: Adult equivalence scale — Age category Male Female Less than 1 year 0.41 0.41 l - 3 years 0.56 0.56 4 - 6 years 0.76 0.76 7 - 9 years 0.91 0.91 10 - 12 years 0.97 1.08 13 - 15 years 0.97 1.13 16 - 19 years 1.02 1.05 20 - 39 years 1.00 1.00 40 - 49 years 0.95 0.95 50 - 59 years 0.90 0.90 60 — 69 years 0.90 0.80 70 and older 0.70 0.70 Source: Calculated from caloric requirements for "moderate activity" established by the World Health Organization and the Food and Agriculture Organization (see Ministere du Plan, 1998: Annex B). APPENDIX C COEFFICIENTS AND T STATISTICS FOR REGRESSION MODELS 267 Table C-1: Coefficients of the unrestricted SUR model of rural demand Dependent variable constant lnexp lnexp2 adults children fem hh (share) 80 81 32 71 72 73 SORGH 115.82 -l6.19 0.79 -0.04 0.00 -0.37 t 2.35 -1.75 1.69 -0.31 0.04 -1.12 RICE -37.86 5.79 -0.28 -0.05 0.08 0.40 t -l.09 0.89 -0.84 -0.63 1.44 1.75 CASSA -125.78 22.14 -1.30 -0.18 -0.07 0.56 t -0.74 0.69 -0.80 -0.46 -0.23 0.49 SWPOT 604.61 -98.44 4.41 -0.84 -0.25 0.88 T 3.05 -2.64 2.33 -l.78 -0.74 0.66 WHPOT -29l.40 68.33 -3.33 0.20 0.30 0.12 t -1.87 2.33 -2.24 0.55 1.13 0.11 BANAN 51.98 -15.77 0.82 0.09 0.16 0.93 t 0.32 -0.52 0.54 0.24 0.59 0.87 BEANS -308.30 70.83 -4.03 -l.66 -0.85 1.47 t -1.21 1.47 -1.65 -2.73 -l.95 0.86 PEAS -30.56 11.62 -0.59 -0.17 —0.12 -0.24 t -0.42 0.86 -0.86 -l.00 -0.99 -0.50 TOMAT -2.75 0.20 -0.01 -0.02 0.01 0.09 t -0.28 0.11 -0.13 -0.67 0.56 1.39 BEEF -10.59 -l.14 0.11 0.09 0.04 0.28 t -0.21 -0.12 0.22 0.78 0.47 0.83 MEAT -52.93 7.48 -0.30 -0.10 0.35 -l.ll t -0.52 0.39 -0.32 -0.43 2.04 -l.64 BBEER -101.47 4.32 -0.04 0.15 -0.37 -4.62 t -0.47 0.11 -0.02 0.29 —l.00 -3.20 SBEER -103.13 26.46 -l.30 0.42 -0.11 -0.61 t -0.87 1.18 -l.15 1.47 -0.57 -0.77 FBEER 50.98 -15.23 0.86 0.07 0.03 -0.58 t 0.88 -1.39 1.54 0.54 0.33 -1.48 OIL -54.17 10.71 -0.52 0.15 0.05 -0.25 t -l.51 1.58 -l.52 1.71 0.83 -l.04 SALT -13.79 3.55 -0.20 -0.10 -0.05 -0.05 t -0.73 0.99 -l.l3 -2.20 -1.54 -0.36 SUGAR -lO.36 3.55 -0.16 0.05 0.08 0.17 t -0.39 0.71 -0.64 0.75 1.72 0.94 CLOTH -12.78 2.63 —0.09 0.93 -0.37 -0.02 t -0.12 0.12 -0.08 3.46 -1.93 -0.03 HOUSE 421.36 -92.54 5.04 0.74 0.82 1.55 t 2.73 -2.95 3.17 1.90 2.93 1.41 EQUIP -40.57 6.74 -0.25 0.08 0.12 -0.38 t -0.48 0.39 -0.29 0.39 0.80 -0.62 ENERG -4.67 1.69 -0.10 -0.07 -0.23 -0.11 t -0.10 0.18 -0.21 -0.61 -2.62 -0.32 HEALT -l4.39 3.30 -0.17 0.15 -0.06 0.03 t -0.33 0.37 -0.38 1.37 -0.74 0.11 EDUCA -21.66 4.30 -0.21 0.14 0.10 -0.03 t -0.63 0.62 -0.61 1.60 1.62 —0.10 TRANS 21.38 -5.33 0.33 —0.03 0.09 0.21 t 0.52 -0.64 0.78 -0.31 1.14 0.73 TOBAC 3.58 -0.41 0.01 0.03 -0.08 -0.19 t 0.13 -0.08 0.05 0.43 -l.73 -1.01 LEISU -l7.54 3.34 -0.15 -0.03 0.02 -0.25 t -0.50 0.47 -0.42 -0.28 0.31 -0.99 268 Dependent variable SOR RICE CAS SWPT WHPT BAN BEAN PEAS (share) ail ¢i2 ai3 ai4 ai5 ai6 ai7 ai8 SORGH 0.23 -0.58 -0.48 -0.88 -l.10 -0.63 0.77 0.13 t 0.24 -0.41 —1.22 -2.10 -l.40 -2.33 1.13 0.19 RICE 0.76 -0.76 0.11 -0.19 0.83 0.05 0.88 0.37 t 1.10 -0.76 0.40 -0.66 1.50 0.28 1.84 0.77 CASSA 1.83 -1.18 -0.56 —0.84 2.90 0.72 -1.69 0.94 t 0.54 -0.24 -0.42 -0.58 1.07 0.78 -0.72 0.40 SWPOT 2.48 1.93 -l.62 -l.20 4.14 1.01 —0.00 0.89 t 0.64 0.35 -l.05 -0.73 1.33 0.96 -0.00 0.33 WHPOT -1.63 -2.03 1.61 -0.89 -5.75 -2.54 -l.85 2.59 t -0.53 -0.46 1.29 -0.67 -2.30 -3.00 -0.86 1.19 BANAN -3.11 0.76 -2.03 1.32 0.57 0.92 0.84 -3.73 t -0.99 0.17 -l.6l 0.98 0.22 1.07 0.38 -1.69 BEANS -8.18 3.74 6.96 -0.18 -2.33 3.35 2.13-11.54 t —1.65 0.52 3.50 -0.08 -0.58 2.46 0.62 -3.31 PEAS -0.48 -2.66 0.44 -0.59 -0.92 -0.38 0.52 -0.69 t -0.34 -l.30 0.78 -0.96 -0.80 -0.97 0.52 -0.69 TOMAT 0.18 -0.08 0.03 -0.03 0.24 -0.07 0.10 0.00 t 0.92 —0.27 0.39 -0.38 1.50 -1.32 0.76 0.01 BEEF 0.05 0.26 0.32 1.12 0.85 -0.02 0.45 1.29 t 0.05 0.18 0.79 2.62 1.06 -0.06 0.65 1.83 MEAT 6.66 -4.70 -0.77 0.48 -2.06 0.27 0.17 -l.02 t 3.32 -1.63 -0.96 0.56 -1.27 0.50 0.12 -0.72 BBEER -3.19 11.73 -3.08 2.51 2.58 2.12 0.01 3.98 t -0.76 1.95 -l.83 1.40 0.76 1.85 0.00 1.35 SBEER 1.30 2.03 -1.60 -0.51 0.87 -l.21 -2.85 2.50 t 0.55 0.59 -1.68 -0.50 0.45 -1.86 -1.72 1.50 FBEER -0.64 4.13 -0.02 -0.16 0.53 0.15 0.28 1.18 t -0.56 2.51 -0.05 -0.33 0.57 0.49 0.35 1.47 OIL 0.77 -2.52 0.07 0.32 0.84 -0.09 0.12 0.62 t 1.08 -2.47 0.23 1.07 1.47 -0.48 0.24 1.24 SALT -0.54 -l.36 0.16 0.11 0.14 0.14 -0.21 0.01 t —1.46 -2.56 1.05 0.68 0.48 1.42 —0.80 0.04 SUGAR 0.74 -2.69 -0.40 0.11 -0.15 -0.03 0.20 -0.38 t 1.42 -3.59 -l.90 0.50 -0.37 -0.24 0.56 -1.05 269 Dependent variable TOM BEEF MEAT BBR SBR FBR OIL SALT SUGR (share) ai9 ailO aill ai12 ail3 ai14 ails ai16 ail7 SORGH 0.28 —2.03 0.55 0.08 -0.14 -l.73 -2.01 -0.46 0.30 t 0.74 -2.52 0.64 0.15 -0.17 -0.68 -2.50 -0.44 0.75 RICE 0.28 -0.51 -0.03 —0.49 0.11 0.90 0.30 0.17 -0.24 t 1.03 -0.90 -0.05 -1.32 0.19 0.50 0.53 0.24 -0.86 CASSA -1.84 2.78 2.78 2.00 1.07 -0.70 -1.97 2.11 2.30 t -l.40 1.00 0.93 1.11 0.37 -0.08 -0.71 0.58 1.67 SWPOT 3.27 -4.83 -4.03 6.53 -4.86 -2.61 1.49-10.02 -2.76 t 2.19 -1.53 -1.17 3.16 -1.47 -0.26 0.47 -2.44 -1.76 WHPOT -1.43 -3.10 0.43 5.35 -1.14-11.38 3.47 5.92 -0.82 t -1.19 -1.22 0.16 3.22 -0.43 -1.42 1.37 1.79 -0.65 BANAN -0.61 0.97 -l.65-ll.10 3.02 17.37 2.10 -6.48 1.76 t —0.50 0.38 -0.59 -6.59 1.12 2.14 0.81 -1.93 1.37 BEANS -0.62 0.37 5.54 2.86 -1.79 -1.88 -0.52 4.43 2.72 t -0.32 0.09 1.25 1.08 -0.42 -0.15 -0.13 0.84 1.34 PEAS -0.61 -1.52 -0.23 2.13 -0.84 0.71 0.74 -0.97 -0.98 t —l.11 -1.30 -0.18 2.79 -0.69 0.19 0.63 -0.64 -1.68 TOMAT —0.09 -0.11 0.32 -0.27 0.21 0.22 0.16 -0.40 0.11 t —l.19 -0.67 1.81 -2.58 1.27 0.43 0.99 -l.92 1.35 BEEF 0.47 1.12 0.80 -1.11 -0.15 -l.72 0.72 -l.53 0.88 t 1.21 1.36 0.90 -2.08 -0.17 -0.67 0.88 -1.43 2.16 MEAT 0.36 0.93 -0.46 -3.18 0.76 4.35 -0.44 1.60 -0.07 t 0.46 0.56 -0.26 -2.96 0.44 0.84 -0.27 0.75 -0.08 BBEER —l.12 6.05 -6.63 -5.84 6.97 3.33 0.00 1.43 -l.32 t -0.69 1.76 -l.78 -2.60 1.94 0.31 0.00 0.32 -0.77 SBEER 0.19 —5.96 -2.47 4.41 -3.96 -2.56 1.10 1.76 0.54 t 0.21 -3.05 -l.17 3.46 -l.94 -0.42 0.56 0.69 0.56 FBEER 0.44 2.87 -0.94 -0.26 1.62 -6.19 1.38 1.74 -0.92 t 0.99 3.04 -0.92 -0.43 1.65 -2.09 1.47 1.42 —l.97 OIL 0.07 1.62 0.34 -0.21 -0.88 -0.42 0.15 -0.43 -0.05 t 0.26 2.78 0.54 -0.56 -l.45 -0.23 0.26 -0.57 -0.17 SALT -0.27 0.01 0.37 0.10 0.07 1.15 -0.16 0.38 -0.13 t —1.91 0.04 1.13 0.50 0.22 1.20 -0.54 0.95 -0.87 SUGAR 0.26 -0.50 0.85 -0.53 -0.49 0.20 0.54 0.02 -0.13 t 1.30 -1.16 1.83 -l.9l -l.10 0.15 1.27 0.03 -0.62 270 Table C-2: Coefficients of the SUR model of rural demand under symmetry restrictions Dependent variable constant lnexp lnexp2 adults children fem hh (share) 80 81 32 71 72 73 SORGH 101.92 -l7.48 0.84 -0.03 -0.03 -0.31 t 2.21 -1.91 1.83 -0.29 -0.41 -0.97 RICE -30.60 3.29 -0.15 -0.03 0.06 0.43 t -0.92 0.51 -0.46 -0.41 1.03 1.88 CASSA -79.99 20.83 -1.21 -0.09 0.06 0.15 t -0.52 0.66 -0.76 -0.24 0.20 0.14 SWPOT 586.48 -105.13 4.69 -0.86 -0.44 1.53 t 3.25 -2.88 2.54 -1.89 -l.33 1.19 WHPOT -332.08 67.42 -3.30 0.22 0.18 0.13 t -2.34 2.35 -2.27 0.62 0.68 0.13 BANAN -58.35 9.05 -0.38 -0.38 0.34 0.10 t -0.40 0.31 -0.25 -1.03 1.28 0.10 BEANS -366.15 85.34 -4.68 -l.51 -0.55 1.62 t -1.57 1.81 -1.96 -2.55 -1.30 0.97 PEAS -34.63 8.24 -0.44 -0.16 -0.21 -0.26 t -0.52 0.62 -0.65 —0.94 -1.71 -0.55 TOMAT -5.40 0.53 -0.03 -0.02 0.01 0.07 t -0.57 0.28 -0.30 -l.04 0.56 1.07 BEEF -17.76 -1.22 0.12 0.09 0.05 0.27 t -0.38 -0.13 0.25 0.75 0.54 0.82 MEAT -1.02 2.24 -0.04 -0.05 0.32 -l.l3 t -0.01 0.12 -0.04 -0.20 1.88 -1.72 BBEER -8.32 3.41 0.01 0.25 -0.32 -4.89 t -0.04 0.09 0.01 0.51 -0.89 -3.47 SBEER -110.06 24.31 -1.22 0.31 -0.21 -0.55 t -l.01 1.11 -l.10 1.13 -1.08 -0.71 FBEER 67.20 -l6.03 0.89 0.09 0.04 -0.48 t 1.18 -1.47 1.62 0.63 0.40 -l.25 OIL -59.23 9.37 —0.45 0.17 0.04 -0.25 t -1.75 1.40 -l.33 2.02 0.74 -1.06 SALT -l4.66 3.16 -0.18 -0.09 -0.05 -0.05 t -0.79 0.88 -l.01 -1.99 —1.59 -0.41 SUGAR -5.06 1.68 -0.07 0.05 0.06 0.15 t -0.20 0.34 -0.27 0.84 1.33 0.89 CLOTH -12.78 2.63 -0.09 0.93 -0.37 -0.02 t -0.12 0.12 -0.08 3.46 -1.93 -0.03 HOUSE 421.36 -92.54 5.04 0.74 0.82 1.55 t 2.73 -2.95 3.17 1.90 2.93 1.41 EQUIP -40.57 6.74 -0.25 0.08 0.12 -0.38 t -0.48 0.39 —0.29 0.39 0.80 -0.62 ENERG -4.67 1.69 -0.10 -0.07 -0.23 -0.11 t -0.10 0.18 -0.21 -0.61 -2.62 -0.32 HEALT -14.39 3.30 -0.17 0.15 -0.06 0.03 t -0.33 0.37 -0.38 1.37 -0.74 0.11 EDUCA -21.66 4.30 -0.21 0.14 0.10 -0.03 t -0.63 0.62 -0.61 1.60 1.62 -0.10 TRANS 21.38 -5.33 0.33 -0.03 0.09 0.21 t 0.52 -0.64 0.78 -0.31 1.14 0.73 TOBAC 3.58 -0.41 0.01 0.03 -0.08 -0.19 t 0.13 -0.08 0.05 0.43 -l.73 -l.01 LEISU -l7.54 3.34 -0.15 -0.03 0.02 -0.25 t -0.50 0.47 -0.42 —0.28 0.31 -0.99 271 Dependent variable SOR RICE CAS SWPT WHPT BAN BEAN PEAS (share) ail ai2 ai3 ai4 ai5 ai6 ai7 ai8 SORGH 0.08 0.25 —0.43 -0.70 -l.20 -0.65 0.29 -0.12 t 0.09 0.43 -1.17 -1.73 -l.78 -2.56 0.45 -0.23 RICE 0.25 0.46 0.12 -0.16 0.67 0.09 1.12 0.08 t 0.43 0.50 0.45 -0.54 1.31 0.47 2.38 0.20 CASSA -0.43 0.12 -2.08 -l.68 2.95 1.04 1.53 0.23 t -l.l7 0.45 -l.80 -1.68 3.05 1.65 1.10 0.46 SWPOT -0.70 -0.16 -l.68 -l.22 0.12 0.84 -0.98 -0.24 t -l.73 -0.54 -1.68 -0.80 0.11 1.18 -0.62 -0.44 WHPOT -1.20 0.67 2.95 0.12 -6.10 -2.39 -l.96 -0.40 t -l.78 1.31 3.05 0.11 -3.25 -3.46 -l.15 -0.49 BANAN -0.65 0.09 1.04 0.84 -2.39 2.63 4.20 -l.00 t -2.56 0.47 1.65 1.18 -3.46 3.80 4.14 -2.83 BEANS 0.29 1.12 1.53 -0.98 -l.96 4.20 -3.78 -1.49 t 0.45 2.38 1.10 -0.62 -1.15 4.14 -1.14 -1.64 PEAS -0.12 0.08 0.23 -0.24 -0.40 -1.00 -1.49 -2.00 t -0.23 0.20 0.46 -0.44 -0.49 -2.83 -1.64 -2.53 TOMAT 0.13 0.15 0.08 -0.03 0.14 -0.05 0.23 -0.02 t 0.81 0.85 1.11 -0.42 0.99 -0.89 1.76 -0.16 BEEF -0.91 -0.21 0.16 1.00 0.20 0.18 0.47 1.04 t -1.59 -0.42 0.42 2.44 0.29 0.69 0.71 2.01 MEAT 1.15 -0.45 -0.24 0.26 -1.26 0.10 1.52 -0.72 t 1.64 -0.81 -0.32 0.33 -1.03 0.20 1.18 -0.91 BBEER -0.37 -0.57 -2.60 3.33 5.42 -l.53 -l.36 1.36 t -0.75 -l.59 -2.39 2.63 4.16 -1.88 -0.72 1.99 SBEER 0.32 0.52 -0.42 -0.17 -l.62 -0.50 -2.00 -0.13 t 0.44 0.94 -0.51 -0.19 -1.29 -0.87 -l.37 -0.l6 FBEER -l.04 2.91 0.12 -0.27 0.79 0.24 0.58 1.08 t -1.07 2.59 0.28 -0.56 0.90 0.80 0.74 1.50 OIL -0.22 -0.36 -0.09 0.31 1.18 -0.08 0.33 1.10 t -0.47 -0.80 -0.35 1.07 2.43 -0.46 0.71 2.88 SALT -0.43 -0.65 0.07 0.10 0.29 0.08 -0.31 0.12 t -1.31 -1.61 0.48 0.65 1.03 0.78 -l.20 0.49 SUGAR 0.50 -0.52 -0.27 0.06 -0.31 0.04 0.74 -0.41 t 1.77 -2.10 -l.36 0.26 -0.91 0.33 2.12 -l.55 272 Dependent variable TOM BEEF MEAT BBR SBR FBR OIL SALT SUGR (share) ai9 ai10 aill ai12 ai13 ai14 ai15 ai16 ail7 SORGH 0.13 -0.91 1.15 -0.37 0.32 -l.04 -0.22 -0.43 0.50 t 0.81 -l.59 1.64 -0.75 0.44 -l.07 -0.47 -1.31 1.77 RICE 0.15 -0.21 -0.45 -0.57 0.52 2.91 -0.36 -0.65 -0.52 t 0.85 -0.42 -0.81 -l.59 0.94 2.59 -0.80 -1.61 -2.10 CASSA 0.08 0.16 -0.24 -2.60 -0.42 0.12 -0.09 0.07 -0.27 t 1.11 0.42 -0.32 -2.39 -0.51 0.28 -0.35 0.48 -l.36 SWPOT -0.03 1.00 0.26 3.33 -0.17 -0.27 0.31 0.10 0.06 t -0.42 2.44 0.33 2.63 -0.19 -0.56 1.07 0.65 0.26 WHPOT 0.14 0.20 -1.26 5.42 -l.62 0.79 1.18 0.29 -0.31 t 0.99 0.29 -1.03 4.16 -1.29 0.90 2.43 1.03 -0.91 BANAN —0.05 0.18 0.10 -l.53 -0.50 0.24 -0.08 0.08 0.04 t -0.89 0.69 0.20 -l.88 -0.87 0.80 -0.46 0.78 0.33 BEANS 0.23 0.47 1.52 -1.36 -2.00 0.58 0.33 -0.31 0.74 t 1.76 0.71 1.18 -0.72 -1.37 0.74 0.71 -1.20 2.12 PEAS -0.02 1.04 -0.72 1.36 -0.13 1.08 1.10 0.12 -0.41 t -0.16 2.01 -0.91 1.99 -0.16 1.50 2.88 0.49 -1.55 TOMAT -0.04 0.01 0.25 -0.15 0.15 0.04 0.09 -0.26 0.06 t -0.62 0.10 1.67 -l.47 0.99 0.13 0.68 -2.34 0.88 BEEF 0.01 0.31 0.80 -0.53 -l.31 1.64 1.05 -0.11 0.34 t 0.10 0.41 1.16 -l.05 -1.79 1.97 2.48 -0.38 1.26 MEAT 0.25 0.80 -1.00 -3.78 -0.51 -0.44 -0.55 0.12 0.47 t 1.67 1.16 -0.64 -3.88 -0.43 -0.46 -l.ll 0.40 1.33 BBEER -0.15 -0.53 -3.78 -l.66 4.32 -0.14 -0.42 0.14 -0.54 t -1.47 -1.05 -3.88 -0.82 3.89 -0.24 -1.19 0.74 -2.05 SBEER 0.15 -l.31 -0.51 4.32 -1.87 1.57 -0.86 -0.02 -0.11 t 0.99 -1.79 -0.43 3.89 -l.04 1.69 -l.63 -0.06 -0.28 FBEER 0.04 1.64 -0.44 -0.14 1.57 -6.46 0.97 1.45 -0.52 t 0.13 1.97 -0.46 -0.24 1.69 -2.36 1.26 2.06 -1.28 OIL 0.09 1.05 -0.55 -0.42 -0.86 0.97 0.70 -0.25 -0.20 t 0.68 2.48 -1.11 -1.19 —1.63 1.26 1.37 -0.94 -0.96 SALT -0.26 -0.11 0.12 0.14 -0.02 1.45 -0.25 0.42 -0.19 t -2.34 -0.38 0.40 0.74 -0.06 2.06 -0.94 1.14 -1.36 SUGAR 0.06 0.34 0.47 -0.54 -0.11 -0.52 -0.20 -0.19 -0.41 t 0.88 1.26 1.33 -2.05 -0.28 -l.28 -0.96 -1.36 -2.17 273 Table C-3: Coefficients of the unrestricted SUR model of urban demand Dependent variable constant lnexp lnexp2 adults children fem hh (share) 30 B1 B2 71 72 73 SORGH 14.39 -1.95 0.07 -0.10 -0.03 -0.06 t 0.92 -0.71 0.58 -1.26 -0.78 -0.23 RICE -89.51 17.19 -0.81 -0.13 0.12 -0.06 t -3.63 3.96 -3.95 -1.06 1.73 -0.14 BREAD -37.32 5.27 -0.24 0.09 0.06 0.07 t -4.21 3.36 -3.22 1.95 2.55 0.48 CASSA -15.78 3.27 -0.21 -0.32 0.12 -0.72 t -0.65 0.76 -1.05 -2.54 1.82 -1.76 SWPOT 157.83 —28.57 1.20 -0.37 -0.14 0.39 t 3.65 -3.75 3.35 -l.70 -l.l8 0.54 WHPOT 4.44 10.28 -0.56 -0.19 0.07 0.36 t 0.11 1.45 -l.69 -0.95 0.66 0.53 BANAN 6.21 -1.47 -0.00 -0.05 0.04 1.03 t 0.19 -0.25 -0.01 -0.32 0.39 1.83 CASFL 18.15 -4.20 0.13 0.00 0.17 0.50 t 0.65 -0.86 0.57 0.00 2.22 1.07 BEANS 214.25 —23.30 0.77 -1.26 -0.45 -0.75 t 3.00 -l.84 1.29 -3.49 -2.29 -0.62 PEAS 7.78 0.43 -0.02 -0.00 0.01 —0.17 t 0.76 0.24 -0.28 -0.03 0.20 —l.02 VEGET -24.50 3.98 -0.19 0.13 0.01 0.53 t -2.16 1.98 -2.02 2.29 0.32 2.80 BEEF -102.49 18.83 -0.90 -0.12 0.10 -0.45 t -3.97 4.15 -4.22 -0.90 1.40 -l.05 MEAT -18.28 5.53 -0.26 0.29 0.09 0.03 t —0.75 1.29 -l.26 2.35 1.33 0.07 MILK -88.82 10.18 -0.49 0.33 0.09 0.76 t -2.81 1.82 -l.86 2.06 1.08 1.43 BBEER -98.58 19.19 -0.98 -1.19 -0.63 -4.46 t -l.76 1.93 -2.11 -4.17 -4.12 ~4.74 SBEER 8.92 -0.10 -0.01 -0.15 -0.13 -0.63 t 0.41 -0.03 -0.07 -l.33 -2.19 -1.71 FBEER -73.32 13.07 -0.50 -0.30 -0.08 -2.08 t -1.28 1.30 -l.06 -1.05 -0.52 -2.18 OIL -49.59 10.29 -0.49 -0.00 0.11 0.50 t -3.45 4.05 -4.08 -0.02 2.74 2.08 SALT 2.86 -0.36 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 0.12 t 0.69 -0.49 0.15 -0.34 -1.36 1.76 SUGAR -52.71 11.59 -0.55 -0.01 0.14 1.33 t -2.33 2.91 -2.94 -0.12 2.25 3.51 MEALS 141.19 -l9.41 0.90 -1.15 -0.82 -2.89 t 1.83 -1.43 1.41 —2.93 -3.93 -2.25 274 Dependent variable constant lnexp lnexp2 adults children fem hh (share) 30 B1 B2 71 72 73 CLOTH -47.60 9.81 -0.46 0.22 0.09 -0.36 t -1.24 1.35 -1.33 1.13 0.83 -0.53 HOUSE 290.47 -63.88 3.49 1.26 0.22 1.67 t 2.81 -3.26 3.77 2.42 0.73 0.91 EQUIP -16.53 1.41 0.03 0.21 0.17 0.37 t -0.53 0.24 0.11 1.32 1.87 0.67 ENERG -120.65 22.05 -0.98 0.44 0.22 0.92 t -3.09 2.98 -2.80 2.25 1.98 1.33 HEALT -38.72 7.42 -0.34 0.38 0.11 0.69 t -1.69 1.71 -l.65 3.29 1.63 1.69 EDUCA -29.75 5.25 -0.23 0.12 0.26 1.32 t —1.07 1.00 -0.93 0.85 3.20 2.68 TRANS 60.02 -14.90 0.88 1.22 0.35 1.39 t 0.96 -1.25 1.56 3.86 1.91 1.25 TOBAC -34.51 7.59 -0.38 -0.16 -0.19 -1.03 t -1.83 2.13 -2.28 -1.71 -3.46 -3.09 LEISU 15.45 -4.25 0.26 0.79 0.04 0.40 t 0.72 -1.04 1.35 7.28 0.69 1.04 275 Dependent variable SOR RICE BRD CAS SWPT WHPT BAN CSFL BEAN PEAS VEG (share) ail ui2 ai3 ai4 aiS ai6 ai7 ai8 ai9 ailO aill SORGH -0.48 0.20 -0.03 0.09 0.07 0.59 -0.36 0.13 0.70 -0.19 -0.30 t -l.37 0.26 -0.09 0.29 0.22 0.84 -1.64 0.38 1.29 -0.55 —0.87 RICE 0.46 -3.77 0.26 -0.56 1.32 -0.89 0.11 0.13 2.09 0.00 0.32 t 0.82 —3.00 0.57 -1.14 2.54 -0.79 0.31 0.25 2.41 0.00 0.58 BREAD 0.18 0.25 0.23 0.01 0.16 -0.51 -0.05 0.39 0.40 0.34 -0.18 t 0.92 0.56 1.47 0.06 0.89 -1.30 -0.39 2.06 1.33 1.79 -0.94 CASSA -0.30 -1.94 -0.36 2.01 -0.15 1.73 -0.22 0.20 -1.03 -0.31 0.20 t -0.55 -1.56 -0.79 4.15 -0.29 1.55 -0.64 0.38 -l.20 -0.57 0.37 SWPOT -2.82 3.79 0.02 0.52 -1.88 5.84 -0.91 -0.06 -0.88 3.36 -l.15 t -2.95 1.76 0.03 0.62 -2.11 3.03 -l.51 -0.07 -0.60 3.58 -1.20 WHPOT -0.03 1.69 0.47 -0.01 -1.07 -1.61 -0.70 -1.80 2.50 -2.93 -1.45 t -0.04 0.84 0.65 -0.01 -1.29 -0.90 -1.24 —2.09 1.80 -3.34 -1.62 BANAN -0.35 0.53 0.14 -0.28 -0.96 1.38 -0.90 0.54 0.29 -0.02 -0.22 t -0.46 0.31 0.23 -0.42 -1.37 0.91 -1.89 0.74 0.25 -0.02 -0.29 CASFL 0.67 0.42 0.01 -0.35 0.80 1.10 -0.35 -l.l9 -0.35 0.03 0.27 t 1.06 0.29 0.01 -0.64 1.36 0.86 -0.89 -l.95 -0.35 0.05 0.43 BEANS -2.06 -0.67 —0.39 -0.45 -3.45 1.19 -0.99 -0.18 2.98 -2.63 0.14 t -1.35 -0.19 -0.31 -0.34 -2.42 0.39 -1.03 -0.12 1.26 -1.76 0.09 PEAS -0.03 0.20 -0.16 -0.00 0.07 -1.75 -0.10 -0.52 0.48 -0.16 -0.16 t -0.14 0.39 -0.84 -0.00 0.33 —3.74 -0.71 -2.35 1.34 -0.69 -0.67 VEGET 0.43 -0.60 0.20 -0.11 0.45 0.45 0.06 -0.16 0.29 0.15 -0.21‘ t 1.72 -1.08 1.01 -0.51 1.95 0.90 0.38 -0.67 0.77 0.63 -0.84 BEEF 0.20 -0.53 0.44 1.26 1.70 ~0.30 -0.36 0.28 0.22 -0.80 0.19 t 0.34 -0.40 0.93 2.48 3.15 -0.26 -0.99 0.51 0.24 -l.40 0.33 MEAT 0.83 -3.20 -1.24 0.07 0.53 0.52 0.28 -0.10 -0.94 -0.57 0.17 t 1.53 -2.60 -2.79 0.14 1.03 0.47 0.80 -0.19 -l.ll -1.06 0.31 MILK -0.67 2.55 0.28 1.41 -0.22 -1.06 -1.03 -0.12 3.18 1.22 -0.08 t -0.95 1.62 0.49 2.29 -0.34 —0.75 -2.33 -0.18 2.92 1.78 -0.11 BBEER —0.41 7.06 0.66 0.86 1.13 3.17 0.85 3.25 -2.83 0.42 -0.52 t -0.34 2.55 0.66 0.80 0.99 1.28 1.10 2.74 -1.49 0.35 -0.43 SBEER -0.20 -1.15 0.06 0.03 -0.98 0.28 0.20 0.81 0.48 -l.02 -0.62 t -0.42 -1.05 0.15 0.07 -2.16 0.29 0.66 1.74 0.64 -2.15 -1.29 FBEER 0.78 0.14 -0.88 -2.78 0.90 -3.04 1.00 0.46 -3.53 -0.80 0.18 t 0.62 0.05 -0.86 -2.52 0.76 -1.20 1.26 0.38 -1.81 -0.65 0.15 OIL 0.45 -0.70 -0.14 0.23 0.71 0.14 -0.26 -0.10 0.28 -0.00 -0.24 t 1.40 -0.98 -0.55 0.82 2.39 0.22 -l.29 —0.33 0.56 -0.01 -0.77 SALT —0.11 0.10 -0.01 0.01 0.05 0.00 -0.09 0.05 -0.01 -0.07 -0.12 t -1.17 0.49 -0.08 0.12 0.61 0.02 -l.46 0.59 -0.06 -0.77 -l.24 SUGAR 0.69 -2.04 0.50 -0.09 1.08 -0.74 —0.87 -l.00 0.88 0.86 -0.25 t 1.37 -l.81 1.22 -0.20 2.32 -0.73 -2.76 -2.09 1.13 1.75 —0.49 MEALS 3.13 -2.58 0.09 -0.59 0.61 -6.09 3.73 -1.26 -4.43 2.31 3.79 t 1.79 -0.66 0.06 -0.38 0.37 -1.73 3.38 -0.75 -1.63 1.35 2.17 276 Dependent variable BEEF MEAT MILK BBR SBR FBR OIL SALT SUGR MEAL (share) ai12 ai13 ail4 ailS ail6 ai17 ai18 ail9 ai20 ai21 SORGH 0.11 0.10 -0.06 0.17 -0.65 0.15 -0.47 0.03 0.13 -0.12 t 0.36 0.33 -0.20 0.57 -l.92 0.30 —2.35 0.06 0.61 -0.74 RICE 0.56 -0.04 0.43 0.51 -0.91 0.43 0.08 -0.57 0.35 -0.01 t 1.19 -0.08 0.91 1.08 -1.67 0.54 0.25 -0.67 1.02 -0.02 BREAD -0.02 0.14 0.25 -0.01 -0.23 -0.07 0.15 0.06 -0.04 0.22 t -0.13 0.84 1.53 -0.06 -1.20 -0.26 1.34 0.20 -0.30 2.32 CASSA —0.69 -0.27 1.02 0.26 1.98 0.31 0.22 0.08 0.36 0.12 t —1.48 -0.58 2.18 0.55 3.67 0.39 0.70 0.10 1.05 0.47 SWPOT -0.14 -0.26 -0.20 -0.22 -l.06 —1.58 -0.29 0.61 0.71 0.34 t ~0.18 -0.32 -0.25 -0.27 -1.13 ~1.15 -0.54 0.42 1.20 0.74 WHPOT 0.03 -0.91 -1.17 -0.75 -0.29 -2.55 0.39 1.55 -1.00 -1.12 t 0.04 -1.22 -1.55 -0.98 -0.34 ~1.99 0.76 1.14 -l.81 -2.59 BANAN 0.93 -0.35 -0.52 0.93 2.09 0.10 -0.33 0.10 -0.20 0.40 t 1.46 -0.56 -0.82 1.44 2.84 0.09 ~0.76 0.08 -0.44 1.09 CASFL -0.34 -0.03 -0.32 0.04 1.36 -0.45 -0.03 2.59 0.60 -0.21 t -0.64 -0.06 -0.59 0.08 2.20 -0.49 -0.08 2.69 1.55 -0.68 BEANS 1.08 0.39 -0.17 0.05 -5.43 -1.87 0.29 2.51 -0.30 -1.36 t 0.85 0.30 -0.14 0.04 -3.65 -0.85 0.33 1.08 -0.32 -1.84 PEAS -0.05 -0.09 -0.06 -0.03 -0.40 -0.24 0.10 -0.23 0.15 0.02 t -0.24 -0.45 -0.29 -0.15 -1.75 -0.73 0.73 -0.65 1.07 0.13 VEGET 0.05 0.05 0.25 0.34 -0.09 -0.28 -0.05 -0.19 0.19 0.22 t 0.24 0.23 1.18 1.63 -0.38 -0.80 -0.35 -0.51 1.26 1.84 BEEF -0.25 -0.18 0.23 0.28 -0.19 -0.78 0.39 -0.04 0.01 0.59 t —0.51 -0.38 0.46 0.57 -0.34 —0.94 1.19 -0.05 0.03 2.11 MEAT -0.35 -0.34 0.46 0.38 -l.03 1.68 0.05 0.65 0.23 -0.04 t -0.76 -0.74 0.99 0.82 -1.93 2.15 0.16 0.78 0.69 -0.14 MILK 0.65 -0.58 0.71 0.49 1.73 -0.95 -0.01 0.79 -0.60 0.88 t 1.11 -0.99 1.20 0.83 2.53 -0.95 -0.02 0.74 -1.40 2.61 BBEER -1.67 -1.49 -0.48 -6.30 2.98 1.11 0.24 -l.57 0.04 -0.53 t -1.62 -l.45 -0.47 -6.03 2.49 0.63 0.34 -0.84 0.05 —0.90 SBEER -0.19 -0.10 -0.26 -0.31 -0.98 2.29 0.06 —0.50 0.65 -0.22 t -0.47 -0.24 -0.63 -0.75 -2.08 3.30 0.21 -0.68 2.20 -0.95 FBEER 0.46 2.64 1.12 1.11 -0.71 0.74 -0.15 -2.75 0.62 1.09 t 0.44 2.51 1.06 1.04 -0.58 0.41 -0.21 -1.44 0.80 1.80 OIL 0.11 -0.07 -0.21 0.20 -0.10 -0.66 0.21 -0.65 0.24 0.24 t 0.41 -0.25 -0.79 0.74 -0.33 -1.45 1.13 -l.33 1.22 1.56 SALT 0.03 -0.05 0.01 -0.03 -0.09 -0.05 -0.00 0.60 0.05 -0.08 t 0.38 -0.64 0.19 -0.35 -l.00 -0.36 -0.01 4.26 0.82 -1.73 SUGAR 0.25 -0.19 -1.42 0.55 1.27 -0.91 0.15 -0.38 0.19 0.52 t 0.61 -0.46 -3.38 1.31 2.61 -1.27 0.53 -0.50 0.62 2.16 MEALS -l.27 -0.03 0.97 0.56 1.43 0.10 -0.53 -2.86 -2.11 —0.99 t -0.86 -0.02 0.66 0.38 0.84 0.04 -0.53 -1.08 -1.97 -1.17 277 Table C-4: Coefficients of the SUR model of urban demand under symmetry restrictions Dependent variable constant lnexp lnexp2 adults children fem hh (share) BO 31 82 71 72 73 SORGH 12.43 -1.59 0.06 -0.13 -0.03 -0.07 t 0.85 -0.59 0.44 -1.67 -0.80 -0.28 RICE -99.28 18.87 -0.88 -0.05 0.13 -0.02 t -4.23 4.39 -4.34 -0.41 1.99 -0.05 BREAD -33.80 5.24 -0.24 0.09 0.06 0.11 t -3.99 3.37 -3.23 1.97 2.47 0.77 CASSA -20.51 4.49 -0.26 -0.35 0.14 -0.69 t -0.91 1.06 -1.33 -3.01 2.12 -l.76 SWPOT 200.36 -35.19 1.48 -0.49 -0.19 -0.06 t 5.05 -4.72 4.22 -2.40 -1.67 -0.08 WHPOT -2.46 8.50 -0.49 -0.31 0.10 0.19 t -0.07 1.22 -l.50 -1.59 0.93 0.29 BANAN 15.19 -1.06 -0.02 -0.12 0.04 0.88 t 0.50 -0.19 -0.07 -0.77 0.48 1.64 CASFL 36.55 -5.32 0.18 -0.02 0.15 0.64 t 1.42 -1.11 0.81 -0.12 2.08 1.42 BEANS 196.84 -25.85 0.86 -l.35 -0.48 -0.82 t 2.99 -2.09 1.47 -4.00 -2.55 -0.71 PEAS 4.61 0.02 -0.01 -0.03 0.01 -0.20 t 0.48 0.01 -0.07 -0.68 0.22 -1.20 VEGET -25.46 4.29 -0.20 0.13 0.01 0.57 t -2.36 2.16 -2.19 2.35 0.45 3.04 BEEF -112.44 22.18 -1.05 -0.10 0.11 -0.37 t —4.74 4.99 -5.02 -0.84 1.57 -0.89 MEAT -24.00 5.36 -0.24 0.28 0.08 0.28 t -1.07 1.27 -l.23 2.41 1.24 0.70 MILK -60.41 9.42 -0.45 0.29 0.09 0.63 t -2.07 1.72 -1.75 1.95 1.02 1.23 BBEER -92.91 22.52 -1.14 -1.46 -0.63 -5.03 t -1.82 2.34 -2.51 -5.59 -4.26 -5.57 SBEER 6.49 -0.98 0.02 -0.24 -0.15 -0.65 t 0.32 —0.26 0.13 -2.29 —2.54 -1.84 FBEER -66.84 12.18 -0.45 -0.10 -0.14 -1.93 t -1.27 1.24 -0.98 -0.36 -0.95 -2.09 OIL -57.60 11.15 -0.53 -0.01 0.11 0.55 t -4.29 4.46 -4.47 -0.11 2.98 2.35 SALT 3.49 -0.45 0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.11 t 0.86 -0.62 0.26 -0.44 -l.34 1.54 SUGAR -58.70 11.41 -0.54 0.00 0.17 1.40 t -2.82 2.92 -2.94 0.01 2.80 3.83 MEALS 99.00 -17.51 0.84 -0.79 -0.75 -2.24 t 1.44 -l.34 1.36 -2.24 -3.75 -1.82 278 Dependent variable constant lnexp lnexp2 adults children fem hh (share) BO 31 82 71 72 73 CLOTH -47.60 9.81 —0.46 0.22 0.09 -0.36 t -1.24 1.35 -l.33 1.13 0.83 -0.53 HOUSE 290.47 -63.88 3.49 1.26 0.22 1.67 t 2.81 -3.26 3.77 2.42 0.73 0.91 EQUIP -l6.53 1.41 0.03 0.21 0.17 0.37 t -0.53 0.24 0.11 1.32 1.87 0.67 ENERG -120.65 22.05 -0.98 0.44 0.22 0.92 t -3.09 2.98 -2.80 2.25 1.98 1.33 HEALT -38.72 7.42 -0.34 0.38 0.11 0.69 t -1.69 1.71 -1.65 3.29 1.63 1.69 EDUCA -29.75 5.25 -0.23 0.12 0.26 1.32 t -l.07 1.00 -0.93 0.85 3.20 2.68 TRANS 60.02 -14.90 0.88 1.22 0.35 1.39 t 0.96 -l.25 1.56 3.86 1.91 1.25 TOBAC -34.51 7.59 -0.38 -0.16 -0.19 -1.03 t —l.83 2.13 -2.28 -1.71 -3.46 -3.09 LEISU 15.45 -4.25 0.26 0.79 0.04 0.40 t 0.72 -l.04 1.35 7.28 0.69 1.04 279 Dependent variable SOR RICE BRD CAS SWPT WHPT BAN CSFL BEAN PEAS VEG (share) ail ai2 ai3 ai4 ai5 ai6 ai7 ai8 ai9 ailO aill SORGH -0.28 0.03 -0.07 0.00 -0.19 0.32 -0.23 0.16 0.41 -0.08 0.11 t -0.88 0.07 -0.45 0.01 -0.65 0.67 -l.14 0.59 0.85 -0.43 0.63 RICE 0.03 -3.04 0.22 -0.93 1.19 0.37 0.06 0.50 1.92 0.23 -0.07 t 0.07 -2.91 0.79 -2.28 2.55 0.45 0.20 1.12 2.46 0.70 -0.21 BREAD -0.07 0.22 0.15 -0.02 0.16 -0.14 -0.03 0.39 0.18 0.06 0.08 t -0.45 0.79 1.03 -0.15 0.95 -0.44 -0.28 2.30 0.65 0.51 0.63 CASSA 0.00 -0.93 -0.02 1.50 -0.10 0.98 -0.25 —0.49 0.63 0.23 -0.20 t 0.01 -2.28 -0.15 3.33 -0.25 1.77 -0.86 -1.39 0.97 1.28 -l.12 SWPOT -0.19 1.19 0.16 -0.10 -2.60 1.06 -0.08 0.48 2.66 0.42 0.35 t -0.65 2.55 0.95 -0.25 -3.17 1.54 -0.18 1.04 2.92 2.09 1.73 WHPOT 0.32 0.37 -0.14 0.98 1.06 -0.16 0.07 0.04 1.57 -l.89 0.10 t 0.67 0.45 -0.44 1.77 1.54 -0.11 0.15 0.07 1.43 -4.94 0.27 BANAN -0.23 0.06 -0.03 -0.25 -0.08 0.07 -0.85 -0.12 0.01 0.03 0.14 t -1.14 0.20 -0.28 -0.86 -0.18 0.15 -l.9l -0.35 0.02 0.21 0.97 CASFL 0.16 0.50 0.39 -0.49 0.48 0.04 -0.12 -0.96 0.03 -0.18 -0.07 t 0.59 1.12 2.30 -1.39 1.04 0.07 -0.35 -1.72 0.04 -0.93 -0.36 BEANS 0.41 1.92 0.18 -0.63 -2.66 1.57 0.01 0.03 1.59 0.06 0.33 t 0.85 2.46 0.65 -0.97 -2.92 1.43 0.02 0.04 0.79 0.20 0.98 PEAS -0.08 0.23 0.06 0.23 0.42 -1.89 0.03 -0.18 0.06 -0.13 0.16 t -0.43 0.70 0.51 1.28 2.09 -4.94 0.21 -0.93 0.20 -0.62 1.07 VEGET 0.11 -0.07 0.08 -0.20 0.35 0.10 0.14 -0.07 0.33 0.16 -0.12 t 0.63 -0.21 0.63 -1.12 1.73 0.27 0.97 -0.36 0.98 1.07 -0.59 BEEF -0.03 0.19 -0.04 0.32 0.72 -0.64 -0.13 -0.31 0.48 -0.04 0.03 t -0.15 0.49 -0.27 1.04 1.77 -l.20 -0.47 -0.89 0.74 -0.25 0.20 MEAT 0.10 -0.42 0.01 -0.22 0.53 -l.05 0.24 -0.12 0.69 -O.21 0.04 t 0.42 -1.10 0.08 -0.73 1.35 -1.98 0.85 -0.36 1.09 -1.22 0.22 MILK -0.18 0.47 0.21 1.09 0.49 -1.26 -0.65 -0.06 0.50 0.05 0.25 t -0.69 1.15 1.43 3.18 1.04 -2.15 -l.92 -0.15 0.67 0.29 1.40 BBEER 0.14 0.68 -0.01 0.39 -0.13 -0.55 1.06 0.58 0.86 -0.05 0.41 t 0.51 1.54 -0.03 0.96 -0.22 -0.83 2.31 1.27 0.91 -0.27 2.11 SBEER -0.39 -0.80 -0.30 1.05 -0.90 —0.08 0.70 1.33 0.96 -0.45 -0.05 t -l.55 -1.86 —l.86 3.40 -2.36 -0.15 2.66 3.92 1.56 -2.38 -0.27 FBEER 0.12 0.49 -0.17 -l.07 -0.4l -l.24 0.26 -0.33 1.87 0.01 -0.35 t 0.28 0.70 -0.65 -l.82 -0.51 -1.25 0.45 -0.50 1.45 0.02 -1.15 OIL -0.25 -0.12 0.09 0.26 0.67 0.07 -0.18 0.01 0.08 0.07 -0.14 t -l.62 -0.44 0.90 1.36 2.81 0.22 -1.06 0.05 0.21 0.62 -1.24 SALT -0.01 0.01 0.00 -0.02 0.12 0.03 -0.05 0.09 0.03 -0.05 -0.11 t -0.15 0.06 0.04 -0.21 1.41 0.18 -0.86 1.11 0.21 -0.60 -1.41 SUGAR 0.19 -0.17 0.05 0.14 1.43 -1.03 -0.52 0.13 0.44 0.24 0.10 t 1.02 -0.59 0.44 0.57 4.34 -2.48 -2.21 0.49 0.83 1.84 0.77 MEALS -0.04 -0.10 0.20 -0.01 0.30 -0.83 0.55 -0.37 0.49 0.04 0.16 t -0.27 -0.38 2.19 -0.06 0.71 -2.02 1.69 -1.28 0.73 0.38 1.40 280 Dependent variable BEEF MEAT MILK BBR SBR FBR OIL SALT SUGR MEAL (share) ai12 ail3 ail4 ails ai16 ail7 ai18 ail9 ai20 ai21 SORGH -0.03 0.10 -0.18 0.14 -0.39 0.12 -0.25 -0.01 0.19 -0.04 t -0.15 0.42 -0.69 0.51 -1.55 0.28 -1.62 -0.15 1.02 -0.27 RICE 0.19 -0.42 0.47 0.68 -0.80 0.49 -0.12 0.01 -0.17 -0.10 t 0.49 -l.10 1.15 1.54 -l.86 0.70 -0.44 0.06 —0.59 -0.38 BREAD -0.04 0.01 0.21 -0.01 -0.30 -0.17 0.09 0.00 0.05 0.20 t -0.27 0.08 1.43 -0.03 -1.86 -0.65 0.90 0.04 0.44 2.19 CASSA 0.32 -0.22 1.09 0.39 1.05 -1.07 0.26 -0.02 0.14 -0.01 t 1.04 -0.73 3.18 0.96 3.40 -1.82 1.36 -0.21 0.57 -0.06 SWPOT 0.72 0.53 0.49 -0.13 -0.90 -0.41 0.67 0.12 1.43 0.30 t 1.77 1.35 1.04 -0.22 -2.36 -0.51 2.81 1.41 4.34 0.71 WHPOT -0.64 -1.05 -1.26 -0.55 -0.08 -l.24 0.07 0.03 -l.03 -0.83 t -1.20 -l.98 -2.15 -0.83 -0.15 -1.25 0.22 0.18 -2.48 -2.02 BANAN -0.13 0.24 -0.65 1.06 0.70 0.26 -0.18 -0.05 -0.52 0.55 t -0.47 0.85 -1.92 2.31 2.66 0.45 -1.06 -0.86 -2.21 1.69 CASFL -0.31 -0.12 -0.06 0.58 1.33 -0.33 0.01 0.09 0.13 -0.37 t -0.89 —0.36 -0.15 1.27 3.92 -0.50 0.05 1.11 0.49 -1.28 BEANS 0.48 -0.69 0.50 -0.86 -0.96 -l.87 0.08 -0.03 -0.44 -0.49 t 0.74 -1.09 0.67 -0.91 -1.56 -l.45 0.21 -0.21 -0.83 -0.73 PEAS -0.04 -0.21 0.05 -0.05 -0.45 0.01 0.07 -0.05 0.24 0.04 t -0.25 -l.22 0.29 -0.27 -2.38 0.02 0.62 -0.60 1.84 0.38 VEGET 0.03 0.04 0.25 0.41 -0.05 -0.35 -0.14 -0.11 0.10 0.16 t 0.20 0.22 1.40 2.11 -0.27 -1.15 -l.24 -l.41 0.77 1.40 BEEF -0.07 -O.28 0.18 0.36 -0.03 -1.27 0.13 0.02 -0.18 0.45 t —0.18 -0.97 0.54 0.89 -0.08 -2.22 0.73 0.22 -0.74 1.71 MEAT -0.28 -0.43 0.18 0.41 -0.75 1.62 -0.12 -0.05 -0.03 -0.14 t -0.97 -l.05 0.56 1.04 -2.59 2.90 -0.67 -0.66 -0.15 -0.56 MILK 0.18 0.18 1.25 0.40 0.12 -0.46 -0.02 0.04 -0.87 0.67 t 0.54 0.56 2.32 0.83 0.38 -0.69 -0.09 0.52 -3.18 2.15 BBEER 0.36 0.41 0.40 -5.51 -0.38 0.91 0.31 -0.01 0.45 -0.63 t 0.89 1.04 0.83 -5.72 -1.03 1.08 1.31 -0.09 1.34 -1.21 SBEER -0.03 -0.75 0.12 -0.38 -0.39 2.31 -0.07 -0.10 0.89 -0.06 t -0.08 -2.59 0.38 -1.03 -0.93 4.24 -0.38 -1.17 3.88 -0.27 FBEER -l.27 1.62 -0.46 0.91 2.31 -0.54 -0.61 -0.05 -0.27 1.00 t -2.22 2.90 -0.69 1.08 4.24 -0.34 -l.80 -0.37 -0.58 1.78 OIL 0.13 -0.12 -0.02 0.31 -0.07 -0.61 0.04 -0.01 0.05 0.11 t 0.73 -0.67 -0.09 1.31 -0.38 -1.80 0.26 -0.14 0.38 0.79 SALT 0.02 -0.05 0.04 -0.01 -0.10 -0.05 -0.01 0.49 0.01 -0.07 t 0.22 -0.66 0.52 -0.09 -l.l7 -0.37 -0.14 3.86 0.14 -l.52 SUGAR -0.18 -0.03 -0.87 0.45 0.89 -0.27 0.05 0.01 0.04 0.35 t -0.74 -0.15 -3.18 1.34 3.88 -0.58 0.38 0.14 0.14 1.55 MEALS 0.45 -0.14 0.67 -0.63 -0.06 1.00 0.11 -0.07 0.35 -1.25 t 1.71 -0.56 2.15 -l.21 -0.27 1.78 0.79 -1.52 1.55 -1.57 \l w yrs....:. filly-LA .31}... \ :Gloitl . Ill: .1 00:15.?- a. .. "drudnwuuvuwuyfl . I» “A...“ but"? . Ymtiz‘... , :3va Anna... i'avi‘ 1”! II. Eli-’ialo JA‘ . m$§.,._.u. dub , i... .iicthilf. “first m. 7 15...... .. .1: . 2”. figs}: 1.3% 3 ~ J‘A :4 .. 1 r S -\ uh.xum»n..uu..§u.w.. 1..: 3......) Lawn»: .. MEI; A: a... sun, .37.“. i. .t‘llt 1371‘. :3? ...I (gill \ ‘3- "ilun'. a Qua..- l zuhjfii. 3!“. :I...:!.:, a)! 1..]: ; is...