LIBRARY M'chlaan State nlverslty PLACE It RETURN BOX to man this chock“ fun you: noon]. To AVOID FINES Mom on or baton duo duo. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE ‘ ; a p . ‘ , HEW" [ 9 . , JAf¥' g 0 209‘; 6 MSU I: An Nfimdlvo Action/Equal Opportunlty Institution mans-9.1 m—u _» 7i&‘___.‘, ,7 COOPERATIVES, MARKETING ORDERS AND BALANCING SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN THREE PERENNIAL CROP COMMODITY SUBSECTORS By Donald Lee Hinman A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1994 M M m filer ABSTRACT COOPERATIVES, MARKETING ORDERS AND BALANCING SUPPLY AND DEMAND IN THREE PERENNIAL CROP COMMODITY SUBSECTORS By Donald L. Hinman Perennial crop industries have tried different approaches and have had different experiences in attempting to balance supply and demand. Three crops (tart cherries, almonds, and raisins) were selected for comparative analysis of actual and potential roles of various vertical market coordination institutions in improving subsector supply-demand balance. Two significant problems complicate the coordination of supplies with demand in perennial crop subsectors: 1) short-run problems due to annual fluctuations in supplies and 2) long-run challenges relating to substantial overplanting that can result in persistent overproduction. The combination of inelastic demand and annual supply fluctuations results in wide price fluctuations for some commodities. Types of cooperatives and alternative marketing strategies employed by cooperatives were investigated. Committed integrated marketing cooperatives (CIMCs) in the almond and raisin subsectors market a significant portion of member production through strong national branded consumer products. In their roles as food manufacturers, these CIMCs work through their brand position to influence consumer demand and retailer merchandising. They have the ability to significantly influence the demand side in order to help balance subsector supply and demand. A committed commodity marketing cooperative (CCMC) lacks a strong national brand franchise, but focuses on selling large volumes of processed products to food manufacturers and the food service industry along with retaining a commitment to being a reliable supplier of a commodity such as tart cherries. approa. Raisin Diversi incentb orders. mmmc Pooh a deliver Pmduc “On-pr ”PPM: W , . [thlhy “b Long run supply-demand balancing approaches that were investigated included approaches to reduce acreage when overplanting had occurred and to avoid overplanting. Raisin acreage reduction has been accomplished to some degree through the Raisin Diversion Program (RDP) as part of the raisin marketing order. An orchard removal incentive program for tart cherries was proposed but never implemented. Supply management programs were analyzed, with emphasis on federal marketing orders. Three main types of supply management provisions of federal marketing orders are commonly implemented to mitigate the consequences of annual supply fluctuations. Reserve pools address the problem of annual supply fluctuation through storing a portion of grower deliveries in large-crop years and releasing some or all of the storage reserve in short-crop years. Market allocation provides another stabilization approach by removing excess product in large crop years from the designated major markets. The third set of provisions, non-production or non-harvest diversion, provides additional flexibility in managing excess supplies. A major contribution has been to alleviate some of the negative consequences of supply instability by helping to promote increased sales and to prevent erosion of demand through more stable commodity supplies. Supply management provisions of the federal marketing orders have also helped dampen price declines in large crop years, thus mitigating the negative impact on growers. Econometric models of the tart cherry and almond industries were developed to estimate the impact on grower prices of implementing a federal marketing order in each of those two subsectors. Estimated price impacts were substantial in some years of marketing order implementation (up to a 20% difference in grower prices for tart cherries), but impacts were moderate in other years. To my mother, Jean S. Hinman ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I owe a significant debt of gratitude to two people who contributed greatly to the completion of this research. Dr. James Shaffer, my major professor, suggested the general topic, provided overall guidance and was instrumental in obtaining the funding that made this project possible. Dr. Donald Ricks, my research supervisor, provided valuable insights into the workings of perennial crop subsectors and spent countless hours of his time to give me guidance, recommendations, and encouragement. Both of them read several drafts and offered comments that continually improved the dissertation. The thoroughness which Dr. John Staatz brought to the task of reading and editing the dissertation was both a blessing and a curse. His numerous incisive comments and suggestions greatly improved the final document. Dr. Christopher Peterson and Dr. Thomas Pierson also served on my dissertation committee and provided helpful insights. Thanks to each of you. The patient support offered by my wife, Susan Allen, was another necessary ingredient of my success. Nor will I forget the gentle needling and words of encouragement coming from my two stepchildren, Glenn and Virginia. I look forward to spending more time with you all. mm m‘bI—JH TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ....................................................... List of Figures ....................................................... CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION ........................................ Research Objectives ............................................. Research Methods .............................................. CHAPTER 2: SUPPLY-DEMAND BALANCING PROBLEMS ................ A Short-run Supply Issue: Challenges to Coordinating Supply and Demand Because of Annual Supply Fluctuations ........................ Long-Term Supply Trends and Overproduction ....................... Tart Cherry Supply-Demand Balancing Problems ..................... Almond Supply-Demand Balancing Problems ........................ Raisin Supply-Demand Balancing Problems .......................... Long-Run Raisin Supply-Demand Balance Issues ................ Concluding Comments .......................................... CHAPTER 3: THE SUBSECI‘ OR FRAMEWORK ........................ The Subsector Framework ....................................... The Price System and Vertical Coordination ......................... Example of Vertical Coordination Problems: The Behavior of Food Retailers and Manufacturers .......... Other Factors Affecting Price Transmission in the Subsector .................................. The Impact of Annual Supply Variation ....................... Analysis of the Effects of Merchandising ................ The Impact of Merchandising ......................... Consumer Demand: Matching Product Attributes to Consumer Preferences ....................................... Market Coordination Mechanisms and Balancing Subsector Supply and Demand ............................................... Advantages of Cooperatives ...................................... Types of Cooperatives and Balancing Supply and Demand .............. Summary .................................................... vi XII 1 3 4 6 6 16 20 3O 35 37 42 43 46 61 61 67 71 74 76 81 CRAFT CHAPTER 4: DEMAND ISSUES AND COORDINATION .................. 85 Demand Expansion and Cooperatives .............................. 85 Commodity Marketing .......................................... 86 Undifferentiated Commodity Markets and Annual Supply Fluctuations ...................................... 87 Brand/Value-Added Marketing ................................... 88 Elements of Brand / Value-Added Strategies: Advertising, Promotion, and Merchandising Activities ......................... 89 Demand Expansion and Contraction in Response to Annual Supply Fluctuations ........................... 91 Elements of Brand/Value-Added Strategies: Market Development . . 93 Elements of Brand/Value-Added Strategies: Market Research and Product Development ............................... 94 Product Development: Branded Consumer Products ....... 96 Product Development: Value-Added Ingredients .......... 100 Demand Expansion Responses for Extended Periods of Overproduction . . . . 103 Response to Overproduction by the Almond Marketing Cooperative ...................................... 104 Example of Raisin Generic Promotion as a Response to Overproduction .................................... 106 Generic Demand Expansion: Interrelationships with Other Marketing Efforts ................................................ 107 Cooperative Efforts to Reflect Demand Expansion Results to Grower Members .............................................. 109 Summary .................................................... 113 CHAPTER 5: USES OF SUPPLY-DEMAND BALANCING APPROACHES IN THREE PERENNIAL CROP SUBSECTORS ....................... 117 A Short-run Supply Issue: Problems in Coordinating Supply and Demand Because of Annual Supply Fluctuations ....... 117 Federal Marketing Order Supply Management Programs ............... 121 Goals of Federal Marketing Order Programs ................... 121 Reserve Pool Storage with Federal Marketing Orders ............ 123 Market Allocation ....................................... 125 Non-harvest or Non-production Diversion ..................... 127 Non-harvest Diversion Under the Tart Cherry Marketing Order ..................................... 127 Non-production Diversion Under the Raisin Marketing Order ..................................... 128 The Tart Cherry Federal Marketing Order .................... 130 A Proposed New Federal Marketing Order Program ....... 133 A Proposed Supply Management Program Through a Cooperative ................................ 134 Summary of Tart Cherry Supply Management ............ 135 The Almond Federal Marketing Order ....................... 136 vii The Raisin Federal Marketing Order ......................... 140 Comparison of Marketing Order Supply Management in the Tart Cherry, Almond, and Raisin Subsectors ................. 145 A Long-Run Supply Issue: Reducing Acreage Through Orchard or Vine Removal ............................................... 149 A Long-Run Supply Issue: Approaches to Avoid Overplanting ........... 152 Market Information and Projections ......................... 153 Limiting Cooperative Membership ........................... 154 Stock Tonnage Contracts .................................. 155 Acreage Contracts ....................................... 157 Interrelationships Between Demand Expansion and Supply Management . . . 158 Summary .................................................... 159 CHAPTER 6: SIMULATION OF FEDERAL MARKETING ORDER PRICE IMPACI‘S ................................................... 165 Tart Cherry Marketing Order Simulation ........................... 166 The Tart Cherry Model ................................... 167 Bearing Acreage and Production ...................... 170 Carryin Stocks, and Seasonal Supply .................... 172 US. Domestic Demand and Market Allocation ........... 176 The Full Model and Solution Process ................... 179 Overview of Tart Cherry Econometric Model ....... 179 Model Structure Showing Equations and Solution Process .............................. 180 Model Performance ................................ 182 Simulated Alternative Scenario: Non-implementation of Federal Marketing Order .................................. 184 Method of Analysis ................................. 184 Tart Cherry Model Results ........................... 190 Estimated Marketing Order Supply Restriction Impacts for the Five Years of Implementation ........................ 190 Impact of Using the Tart Cherry Marketing Order in Other Large Crop Years ................. 196 Almond Marketing Order Simulation .............................. 200 The Almond Model ...................................... 202 The Estimated Equations ............................ 202 Full Model and Solution Process ...................... 205 Overview of Almond Econometric Model .......... 205 Model Structure Showing Equations and Solution Process .............................. 206 Model Performance ................................ 208 Simulated Alternative Scenario: Non-implementation of Almond Reserve ......................................... 209 Method of Analysis ................................. 210 viii >—-1=.~ ('7 BEUOC AWEND Estimated Price Impacts Without Marketing Order Implementation .............................. 210 Raisin Marketing Order Simulation ................................ 216 Comparison of Three Marketing Order Simulations ................... 221 Suggestions for Model Improvement ............................... 226 CHAPTER 7: SUMMARY AND OVERVIEW ............................ 228 Supply Instability, Uncertainty and Coordination Problems .............. 229 Nature of the Uncertainty Facing Subsector Participants .......... 229 Consequences of Supply Variability in the Three Subsectors ....... 230 Analytical Methods Used to Illustrate Supply-Demand Imbalance . . . 231 Problems of Vertical Coordination Between Subsector Stages ............ 232 The Role of Committed Marketing Cooperatives ..................... 234 Demand Expansion Roles of Committed Marketing Cooperatives . . . 235 Changing Roles of Committed Marketing Cooperatives ........... 239 Future Research on the Role of Committed Marketing Cooperatives ...................................... 240 Long-Run Supply-Demand Balancing ............................... 240 The Role of Supply Management .................................. 243 Supply Management Provisions of Federal Marketing Orders ...... 243 Modeling Federal Marketing Order Price Impacts ............... 244 Differences in Use of Supply Management Among the Three Subsectors ........................................ 247 Applications to Other Commodity Industries ................... 249 Implications for Marketing Order Establishment for Other Commodities . . . 251 The Role of Commodity Promotion and Research Programs ............. 253 Additional Policy Implications .................................... 254 Concluding Comment .......................................... 257 BIBLIOGRAPHY ................................................... 258 APPENDIX A ...................................................... 261 List of Tables Table 1. Production Changes in Four Perennial Crops, 1967-1992 ................ 9 Table 2. Short Versus Large Tart Cherry Crops and Comparison of Revenue and Price ...................................................... 10 Table 3. Short Versus Large Raisin Crops and Comparison of Revenue and Price . . 11 Table 4. Short Versus Large Almond Crops and Comparison of Revenue and Price ....................................................... 12 Table 5. Production Variability Measures For Selected Perennial Crops .......... 15 Table 6. Number of Years from Planting on Bearing and Typical Life Span for Three Perennial Crops .......................................... 18 Table 7. Vertical Stages in Agricultural Subsectors .......................... 43 Table 8. Effects of Temporary Merchandising Techniques on Product Movement . . . 65 Table 9. Food Product Attributes ....................................... 68 Table 10. Examples of Coordinating Mechanisms in Three Perennial Crop Subsectors ................................................... 73 Table 11. Types of Cooperatives in Fruit, Nut, and Vegetable Industries ......... 77 Table 12. Alternative Marketing Strategies in Perennial Crop Subsectors ......... 86 Table 13. Tart Cherry Marketing Order Effect on Supplies .................... 124 Table 14. Short-run Impacts of Marketing Order Supply Management on Firms at Various Subsector Stages ....................................... 161 Table 15. Variable Identification, Tart Cherry Model ........................ 168 Table 16. Structural Relationships of the Tart Cherry Modell .................. 169 Table 17. Bearing Acreage Equation Estimated by OLS ...................... 171 Table 18. Frozen and Canned Pack, Estimated by Seemingly Unrelated Regression ............................ 173 Table 19. Canned Carryin Stocks and Frozen Carryin Stocks Estimated by OLS . . . . 175 Table 20. Three Stage Least Squares Estimates of the US. Demand and Market Allocation System for Tart Cherries ............................... 177 Table 21. Goodness-of-fit Measures of Dynamic Sequential Predictions of Key Endogenous Variables, 1965-1990 ................................. 183 Table 22. Determination and Uses of Restricted Tonnage Under Tart Cherry Marketing Order .............................................. 186 Table 23. Tart Cherry Marketing Order Simulation: Quantities of Cherries Stored and Released ................................................. 187 Table 24. Simulated Impact of Tart Cherry Marketing Order: Estimated Changes in Frozen f.o.b. and Grower Prices in Response to Quantities Stored and Released .................................................... 191 Table 25. Grower Revenue and Net Change in Revenue With and Without Tart Cherry Federal Marketing Order, Based on Simulation Model ........... 195 X Table 26. C Table 27 it Table 28. Table 29. Table 30. Table 31. Table 32. Table 33. M Table 34, In Table 35. 0 Table 36. M Table 37, W Table 26. Determination and Uses of Restricted Tonnage Under Simulation of Tart Cherry Federal Marketing Order .................................. 198 Table 27. Simulation of Tart Cherry Federal Marketing Order Implementation in 1982, 1987, and 1989: Impact on Frozen f.o.b. and Grower Price ........ 199 Table 28. Variable Identification: Almond Model ........................... 201 Table 29. Bearing Acreage Equation Estimated by OLS ...................... 202 Table 30. Domestic Almond Demand Estimated by Three Stage Least Squares . . . . 203 Table 31. Almond Grower Price Equation Estimated by OLS .................. 204 Table 32. Export Sales Equation Estimated by OLS ......................... 205 Table 33. Goodness-of-fit Measures for Dynamic Sequential Predictions of Almond Model Variables, 1973-1989 ...................................... 208 Table 34. Estimated Price and Quantity Changes Without Almond Marketing Order Implementation, 1980-1989 ...................................... 211 Table 35. Estimated Grower Revenue With and Without the Almond Marketing Order Reserve ................................................ 215 Table 36. Tart Cherry Market Supply With and Without Use of the Federal Marketing Order, 1972-1975 ..................................... 261 Table 37. Tart Cherry Supply in Years Following Marketing Order Use, With and Without Market Order Use in 1972, 1975, 1980 ....................... 262 an] ”7; ' L- , :7 f". . (If i -’ '5' '77 ”T7 0: -,-,:-.::- L 7 c! "I 7’? 7 (F L. .—.V List of Figures Figure 1. US. Tart Cherry Production and Bearing Acreage, 1950-1991 .......... Figure 2. US. Almond Production and Bearing Acreage, 1950-1991 ............. Figure 3. US. Raisin Production and Raisin Variety Grape Hectares, 1966-1991 . . . . Figure 4. Illustration of Tart Cherry Grower Price Level Changes Due to Changing Long-Term Supply Conditions, 1972-1989 ........................... Figure 5. Relationship of Average Grower Cost to Tart Cherry Price Levels, 1972- 1990 ........................................................ Figure 6. Michigan Tart Cherry Grower Total and Variable Cost with Yield of 2.6 Tons/Acre ................................................... Figure 7. Michigan Tart Cherry Grower Prices Compared to Variable and Total Cost at Average Yield Each Year ................................. Figure 8. Michigan Tart Cherry Grower Total and Variable Cost and Revenue Per Acre ....................................................... Figure 9. Average U.S. Tart Cherry Production, Average Sales, and Bearing Acreage ..................................................... Figure 10. US. Total Tart Cherry Production and Total Sales, 1950-1991 ......... Figure 11. US. Average Almond Production and Average Sales ............... Figure 12. Domestic and Export Almond Sales, 1964-1991 .................... Figure 13. US. Almond Production and Total Sales ......................... Figure 14. Raisin Type Grape Bearing Acreage and Acreage Harvested for Raisins ...................................................... Figure 15. Harvested Acres, Average Production and Average Sales for NTS Raisins ...................................................... Figure 16. Percentage of Raisin Type Grapes Dried for Raisins and Comparison of Quantity of Grapes Dried for Raisins versus Quantity in All Other Uses, 1966-91 ..................................................... Figure 17. Comparison of California Raisin Grower Price and Production Cost . . . . Figure 18. US. Total Raisin Production and Total Sales, 1964-1991 ............. Figure 19. Simplified Overview of Main Marketing Channels in Processed Perennial . Crop Subsectors .............................................. Figure 20. Demand Schedule with Pricing on the Nines by Grocery Retailer ...... ngufe 21. Retail Price and Product Movement for Supply Increase or Decrease . . . ngure 22. Farm Level Demand ......................................... FlSure 23. Effect of Supply Increase on Tart Cherry Grower Price per Pound ..... Figure 24 Effect of Supply Increase on Manufacturer Price per Can, Tart Cherry Pie Fillin Figure FSilliEffeCt of Supply Increase on Retail Price Per Can of Tart Cherry Pie g OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 7 7 7 22 22 24 24 25 27 28 31 32 33 36 37 39 40 41 45 48 49 51 52 AMT Figure Figure Figure Figure M31 Figure Flgare Figure Tigm’e rt\.\'l ANNUAL SUPPLY DECREASE: FOUR SUBSECT OR STAGES (Fig. 26 through Fig. 29) Figure 26. Impact of Supply Decrease on Growers (Stage One) ................ 56 Figure 27. Impact of Supply Decrease on Processors (Stage Two) .............. 56 Figure 28. Impact of Supply Decrease on Manufacturers (Stage Three) .......... 57 Figure 29. Impact of Supply Decrease on Retailers (Stage Four) ............... 57 ANNUAL SUPPLY INCREASE: FOUR SUBSECTOR STAGES (Fig. 30 through Fig. 33) Figure 30. Impact of Supply Increase on Growers (Stage One) ................ 59 Figure 31. Impact of Supply Increase on Processors (Stage Two) ............... 59 Figure 32. Impact of Supply Increase on Manufacturers (Stage Three) ........... 60 Figure 33. Impact of Supply Increase on Retailers (Stage Four) ................ 60 ANNUAL SUPPLY INCREASE WITH MERCHANDISING: FOUR SUBSECTOR STAGES (Fig. 34 through Fig. 37) Figure 34. Impact of Supply Increase on Growers (Stage One) ................ 62 Figure 35. Impact of Supply Increase on Processors (Stage Two) ............... 62 Figure 36. Impact of Supply Increase on Manufacturers (Stage Three) ........... 63 Figure 37. Impact of Supply Increase on Retailers (Stage Four) ................ 63 Figure 38. Effect of Temporary Merchandising on Retail Demand With Supply Increase ..................................................... 65 Figure 39. Coordination Linkages of Subsector Stages with Consumer Demand . . . . 69 Figure 40. Comparison of Tart Cherry Grower Prices With and Without the Federal Marketing Order, 1972-1986, Based on Econometric Simulation . . . . 193 Figure 41. Comparison of Grower Net Return With and Without Tart Cherry Federal Marketing Order, 1972-1986, Based on Econometric Simulation . . . . 193 Figure 42. Comparison of Actual Almond Grower Price to Simulated Price Without Reserve................. .................................... 214 Figure 43. Mean Grower Prices for Grapes for Drying, 1964-1985: Actual and Alternative Scenarios Based on French and Nuckton Simulation .......... 217 Figure 44. Mean Grower Net Revenue, Grapes for Drying and Crush, 1964-1985: Actual ‘ and Alternative Scenarios Based on French and Nuckton. Simulation ................................................... 217 Figure 45. Raisin Grape Grower Price, Actual and Simulated Without Marketing Order, 1964-1985 .............................................. 220 Figure 46. Grower Net Return to Dry and Crush, Actual and Simulated Without Marketing Order .............................................. 220 Figure 47. Raisin Grape Grower Price, Actual and Simulated Without Marketing Order and With Reduced Planting Response ......................... 220 Figure 48. Grower Net Return to Dry and Crush, Actual and Simulated Without Marketing Order, Reduced Planting Response ....................... 220 misma‘ and bu ofsubs: are ma reasons markets Place w; sum a, is the 0 Mai: @3093 a1 COM?» “12 r,. 0,,h5c Sim a ambled '7? . “Arm C1 CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION The uncertainty facing participants in the food marketing system contributes to mismatches between supply and demand for various agricultural commodities. Both climatic and human factors contribute to this uncertainty. The weather is frequently a major cause of substantial annual supply fluctuations. Human factors are also important in that mistakes are made in agricultural production and investment decisions because of a number of reasons including the difficulty of accurately predicting important economic variables. These factors contribute to problems of economic coordination in commodity markets. Shaffer distinguishes four kinds of coordination.‘ Micro-micro coordination takes place within an individual firm. Micro coordination refers to coordination between firms, such as between firms operating at two adjacent stages of a subsector. Macro coordination is the overall balancing of supply and demand in a commodity subsector in terms of quantities and qualities. Macro-macro coordination refers to the supply and demand of goods and services at the level of the national economy. This research focuses on macro coordination and hereafter all references to coordination mean macro coordination in terms of this classification. The framework used in this research for examining the issues related to matching supply and demand is a subsector approach, which views the flow of an agricultural commodity from grower to consumer through various marketing channels as a vertical system consisting of several stages. Matching supply and demand in terms of both quantities and characteristics of commodities at each stage of the vertical system is part of the process of vertical coordination. There are complex interactions between these stages. Decisions 1James D. Shaffer, "Thinking About Farmers’ Cooperatives, Contracts, and Economic Coordination," in Cooperative Theory: New Approaches, ed. Jeffrey S. Royer, Washington DC: USDA, ACS Service Report 18, July 1987, 61-62. 1 mac take.< sure am Ll. 2 made at various points in the marketing channels for a commodity may help or hinder the match of supply and demand. Mighell and Jones define vertical coordination as "all the ways of harmonizing... at each stage in the vertical production-distribution system."2 The research reported here takes only a slice of that broad concept by focusing on certain means to harmonize the system, specifically, improving the match of quantities supplied and demanded both on an annual basis and over the longer run, and the matching of the characteristics of commodity- based food products with consumer preferences. It also compares the processes of vertical coordination in subsectors with various types of cooperatives, marketing orders, and other coordinating mechanisms. The research gives primary emphasis to certain stages of the vertical market system. Much of the analysis focuses on grower-first handler transactions, which corresponds to stages two and three of the five stages of a subsector as presented in Chapter 2. The analysis concentrates on selected perennial crop commodities. These commodities have significant problems in coordinating supplies with demand. Analysis of those problems provides an opportunity to examine a variety of institutions which have evolved (or have been proposed) to respond to these problems. The study focuses on two supply conditions common to a number of perennial crop subsectors: (1) annual supply fluctuations which are primarily related to weather conditions and (2) long-term changes in acreage and productive capacity that may lead to periods of over-production and under-production relative to typical levels of quantity demanded. The long-run supply-demand balance for many perennial crops is a cyclical type of phenomenon in which periodic overplanting can lead to persistent commodity industry overcapacity 2Ronald Mighell and Lawrence Jones, Vertical Coordinatiop in US. Aggiculture, USDA, Economic Research Service, Farm Economics Division, Agricultural Economics Report No. 19, February 1963. problems. year to In D. perennial 8"er flu consumer Per Capita commodir Pe: 3 problems. At the same time, production of perennial crops often fluctuates sharply from one year to the next. Demand conditions are also significant. Farm-level demand for a number of perennial crops is typically price inelastic. The combination of inelastic demand and annual supply fluctuations results in wide price fluctuations for some commodities. Changes in consumer preferences on product characteristics, such as the trend toward less consumption per capita of sweetened desserts, have also had considerable impact on demand for certain commodity-based processed food products. Perennial crop industries have tried different approaches and have had different experiences in attempting to balance supply and demand. Three perennial crops were selected to be the focus of this analysis: tart cherries, almonds, and raisins. These three crops were selected for comparative analysis because each of them has: (a) faced problems of overproduction at one time or another, (b) developed broad-based programs involving joint industry decision-making to address collective problems, including federal marketing orders, and (c) had large marketing cooperatives playing significant marketing and vertical market coordination roles. 1.1 Research Objectives The first objective of this research is the description and diagnosis of the instability and coordination problems that characterize the markets for each of the three perennial crop commodities. This objective is addressed in chapters two and three. Chapter two examines and compares supply-demand balancing problems for tart cherries, almonds, and raisins. Chapter three introduces the subsector framework and then presents, both conceptually and with examples, problems related to the interaction between subsector stages that hinder effective coordination. intiu: relat. instir price orde; ifder 4 The second objective is to compare the role of various marketing organizations in the three commodity subsectors. To accomplish this, chapter three introduces a system of categorizing market coordination arrangements and their roles in coordinating supply and demand. The third objective is to examine a variety of coordination approaches used to influence demand and supply in the three subsectors. Chapter four focuses on demand- related issues and coordination. Chapter five examines supply management roles and institutions, with particular emphasis on cooperatives and federal marketing orders. Chapter six deals with the fourth objective, which is to assess the impact on grower prices of supply management that has been undertaken through the use of federal marketing orders. Econometric models are developed to analyze the magnitude of the impact of federal marketing orders on tart cherry and almond prices. Comparisons are made with the results of a study of the raisin marketing order. Chapter seven presents a summary and overview of this research, including some perspective on the impact on the commodity subsectors of various market coordination arrangements. 1.2. Research Methods Interviews with a number of participants in the three perennial crop commodity industries provided valuable information on conditions in the three subsectors and approaches used by various firms and organizations to address supply-demand balancing problems. People from cooperatives, the staff of marketing order administrative boards, universities, and government were interviewed. A review of past research, trade publications, as well as cooperative bulletins and newsletters also provided key information. Data on production, sales and prices were collected from a number of published sources, both government and private. Sum bad previou: the analysis research res coordinatior Mar ecunometrir The results r the raisin le To 5 SUFPii'dema 5 Some written portions of this research were reviewed by certain key informants who had previously been interviewed to verify information and obtain additional perspectives on the analysis and issues addressed. This iterative process improved the accuracy of the research results presented herein and also widened the author’s understanding of market coordination arrangements in the three subsectors. Marketing order price and revenue impacts were analyzed by developing econometric models of the tart cherry and almond subsectors. Comparisons were made of the results of these models with previously published research on the economic impact of the raisin federal marketing order. ‘To set the stage for the following chapters, chapter two presents an overview of the supply-demand balancing problems in each of the three perennial crop subsectors. Tu perennial l 2) long-rm persistent Perennial r SUbstantial may not m SUp mmmodiry mm ll inter Pric mate “it dfmand tent item This SUM” Sta Alum Mari). l0 1] CHAPTER 2: SUPPLY-DEMAND BALANCING PROBLEMS IN PERENNIAL CROP SUBSECTORS Two significant problems complicate the coordination of supplies with demand in perennial crop subsectors: 1) short-run problems due to annual fluctuations in supplies and 2) long-run challenges regarding the need to avoid serious overplantings that can result in persistent overproduction. Equilibrium conditions of supply and demand for a number of perennial crops tend to occur infrequently and can be transitory due to the combination of substantial crop fluctuations and long-term trends in orchard or vine capacity which may or may not match demand trends. Supply and demand are in approximate balance when average market prices for a commodity approximate average cost per unit plus a normal return on investment for typical growers. In contrast to the situation of approximate balance, when supplies are excessive grower prices are frequently well below cost of production because total supply is not well coordinated with demand. This chapter examines and compares the supply-demand balancing problems that face each of the three commodities. 2.1. A Short-run Supply Issue: Challenges to Coordinating Supply and Demand Because of Annual Supply Fluctuations Major coordination challenges arise because while supplies of perennial crops can fluctuate widely from year to year largely because of the impact of weather conditions, demand tends to change in a relatively gradual trending pattern over a period of several years. This situation can cause substantial problems for growers and firms at various subsector stages. Although annual supply fluctuations for a number of perennial crops are due primarily to fluctuating yields resulting from variable weather conditions, for a few perennial Figure “We 3. 7 Figure 1. U.S. Tart Cherry Production and Bearing Acreage, 1950-1991 500 f/\ ’70 500- :so ing Acres _ ’5 a: j 5 8 400 ’50 g 35; ~40 = 6 300 < _ g .— U a ’30 ‘ 200- ~ g 35 Prediction ~20 g, _ a: 100 ‘ l- 1 0 o rTTTTTYTTYTTVYTYTYTVTVI‘FYTTTTI'ITYI‘YTT'To 50 53 56 59 62 65 68 71 74 77 80 83 86 89 CropYear Figure 2. U.S. Almond Production and Bearing Acreage, 1950-1991 800 450 700 a “400 J g 600 ‘ Bearing Acres #350 ‘ >300 " 35001 § § ‘ (250 § 3 400 « p (z: - i200 I; l r: 300 i150 g 1 < E 200 s ”00 ‘ Production 100 ‘ r50 o 'U—YTYYYY'U'YVVV'r'VYVW'TYTYT VVVVVV IIIYY—YYYO 50 53 56 59 62 65 68 71 74 77 80 83 86 89 Crwa Figure 3. U.S. Raisin Production and Raisin Variety Grape Acreage, 1966-1991 300 5004 450i Rdsin Variety Grape Bowing Acres " "250 A 400 ‘ g 350 ‘ i- A ‘- < u .0 o ‘ b 8 3004 ”0 § 5 Production __ g ‘6— 250 “ 5 r m § 200 - ”5° ‘52 « 2 O 150‘ " E .. 100 ‘ " 100 ‘i 50 " " 50 o T V V I Y Y T 7 r V I I U 1 V T—Y—Y Y Y Y I T V 1' V 66 68 7O 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 9O Crop Yea crops 1 coninl raisin utilizat produc for rais raisins. Figure m6 0“ dlli in g Ganja-(m 8 crops such as raisins, year-to-year changes in market utilization decisions by growers also contribute to annual supply fluctuations. There have been a few weather-induced short raisin crops in the last 25 years (1972, 1976, 1978). In addition, year-to-year shifts in utilization of raisin-type grapes have also had a significant impact on the quantity of raisins produced in some years. Raisin producers can respond to alternative market opportunities for raisin-type grapes by choosing between selling for crush (wine-making) and drying for raisins. This accounts for some of the year-to-year changes in raisin production shown in Figure 3. In addition, a relatively steady 12-15% are sold for fresh market and for canning. The overall level of raisin-type grape bearing acreage has primarily followed gradual trends during the last 25 years. The reasons for the rise and subsequent decline in the 19708 and 1980s are explored below. Figure 1 and Figure 2 show substantial year to year changes in the level of production of tart cherries and almonds even though the number of bearing hectares changes gradually. Note that in these figures, production level is indicated on the left vertical axis and bearing acreage on the right vertical axis. The magnitude of annual tart cherry supply fluctuations is one of the most pronounced for any U.S. agricultural commodity. Tart cherry supplies are often double or half the level of the previous year. Annual supply fluctuations for almonds increased to some degree in the 19803 as the overall level of supply rose substantially. Perennial crop production variability can be characterized by considering the range of annual change (highest and lowest magnitude) and the number of short crops and large crops that occur in a given time period. Some of this data is summarized in Table 1. Tart cherry annual change in production compared to average shipments of the previous four years ranged between 58% and 180%. Almonds had a similar range (68%-194%), but raisins are somewhat less variable by this measure. However, the number of short crops (10) was significantly greater for tart cherries than for the other crops. 9 Table 1. Production Changes in Four Perennial Crops, 1967-1992 Production as a Percentage of Previous Number of Short and Large Four Years Average Shipmentsl Crops’ Smallest Largest No. of Short No. of Large Percent Percent Crops Crops i Tart Cherries 58 180 10 10 Almonds 68 194 3 14 46 152 4 12 1Based on Table 2, Table 3, and Table 4. The first year of comparative data is 1967 because the earliest year for which there is complete raisin data is 1963. 2 See text for definition of short and large crops. The terms "large crop” and ”short crop" require clarification. In this analysis, a large crop year is defined as a level of production of 120% or more of the average of the previous four years’ shipments. A short crop year is a level of production that is 85% or less of the average of shipments of the previous four years. Table 2 (tart cherries), Table 3 (raisins), and Table 4 (almonds) indicate the general magnitudes of what constitutes large and small crops both in terms of quantity differences and percentage differences between: (a) production in a given year and (b) a four-year moving average of past shipments. The ”large crop year" threshold figure of 120% or more for tart cherries is appropriate because during the operation of the federal marketing order, the administrative board that acted in an administrative and oversight capacity (known as the Cherry Administrative Board) proposed that one or more supply management provisions be implemented, or have issued documents stating that such would be their policy, if crops were of that general magnitude or greater. For raisins, large crops, defined as deliveries by raisin growers of 120% or more of average shipments for the previous four years, generally yield negative net revenue, as Tal Y _ 3 2 are ; 3 Q at... Q Q Q Q me Q Q Q 8.5 Q K fix Rex ......\.. 10 Table 2. Short Versus Large Tart Cherry Crops and Comparison of Revenue and Price +I—F—n Year Crop Short Diff. Between Prod. as Pct. Total Average Annual Price Net Size‘ versus Prod. and Pre- of Previous 4 Reve- Annual as a Pct. of Revenue” (mil. Large vious 4 Yrs. Years Average nue Grower Previous 4 (cents per lbs.) Crop Anghipments Shipments (mil. 3) Price Years Avg. lb.) (mil. lbs.) (¢/lb.) Price 1965 354 large 59 120 16.1 5.0 73 1966 180 short -130 58 24.3 13.8 228 _ 1967 178 short -104 63 30.6 17.5 210 : 1968 276 -2 99 41.5 15.2 147 1969 317 large 71 129 23.3 7.8 61 II 1970 2.51 22 109 17.9 7.6 56 ll 1971 280 41 117 27.7 10.0 83 -0.4 : 1972 312 large 55 121 22.3 8.3 82 -2.0 i 1973 175 short -96 65 33.1 18.9 224 +2.7 1974 265 18 107 48.9 18.5 165 +6.2 1975 291 large 52 122 25.1 10.2 73 4.1 1976 147 short -93 61 36.8 25.1 180 2.1 1977 211 44 121 61.9 29.4 162 + 13.6 1978 181 short -31 85 79.3 43.8 211 +253 " 1979 170 short -31 85 80.5 47.2 174 +235 1980 218 large 39 122 43.3 20.2 56 -3.1 1981 135 short -55 71 59.1 44.5 127 6.8 1982 311 large 138 180 34.6 14.1 36 -9.8 1983 155 short -31 83 71.5 46.6 148 -4.0 1984 255 large 86 147 64.0 25.0 80 -5.6 1985 286 large 103 156 62.8 22.4 69 -5.9 1986 224 22 111 44.3 20.3 75 -14.2 1987 359 large 154 175 22.4 7.8 27 -16.9 1988 236 2 101 43.8 18.7 99 -7.7 1989 264 13 109 35.3 14.5 84 -11.9 1990 209 short 48 81 36.6 18.1 118 -8.4 1991 190 short -64 75 88.1 46.4 313 8.9 1992 335 large 101 143 55.2 17.6 72 -2.5 ‘Crop size, total revenue and price data from Noncitrus Fruits and Nuts (NASS. USDA). Total revenue is farm value. "Average annual U.S. tart cherry grower price minus grower costs per lb.("Cost of Producing Cherries,‘ Mich. St. Univ.) Price «gm PL: MaN fla~ J.\ 321‘ «QN N.\ 13. .N Y. fidN in: 2...... m2...» 23$ NQQWTTEEWEQ ”“3 \W.\ 2m. 11 Table 3. Short Versus Large Raisin Crops and Comparison of Revenue and Price = 1 Difference Prod. as Pct. Annual Net Between Prod. of Previous 4 Revenue Annual Price as a Revenueb and Previous 4 Years Average (mil. 3) Price Pct. of Pre- (5 per ton) tons) Crop Years Average Shipments (3 per vious 4 Yrs. Shipments (mil.lbs.) ton) Avg. Price 19615 241.4 54.0 200 -3 1966 258.2 57.7 206 -9 1967 161.3 short -29 85 53.8 297 1 1968 2405 large 49 126 70.0 266 113 2 II 1969 229.8 large 38 120 66.8 266 110 -2 II 1970 176.3 -17 91 54.6 283 109 -3 I 1971 174.5 - -18 91 63.8 329 118 -6 ! 1972 90.2 short -104 47 58.8 560 196 17 1973 200.7 29 117 168.9 754 210 24 1974 213.1 large 45 127 145.4 602 125 -1 n 1975 252.6 large 83 149 188.2 665 118 -8 1976 134 short -40 77 199.8 706 109 45 ’n 1977 220.3 32 117 208.6 840 123 25 1978 865 short -104 46 243.8 1067 152 108 , 1979 261.7 large 90 152 347.9 1151 140 37 1980 250.6 large 83 149 372.3 1205 128 27 1981 224.4 large 43 124 336.6 1315 123 12 1982 206.2 17 109 336.7 1153 97 -50 1983 336.2 large 125 159 2325 587 49 -50 1984 295 large 78 136 212.4 635 60 -163 1985 303.6 large 74 132 1 211.8 612 66 -135 1986 244.5 -4 98 209.7 757 101 1987 323.1 large 54 120 290.9 817 126 1988 324.1 32 111 326.0 898 127 1989 3933 large 87 128 420.1 977 127 1990 354.9 39 112 354.5 903 105 1991 314.0 25 108 332.2 963 105 1992 353.1 n/a n/a 329.4 ‘Crop size. shipments—Thompson seedless only.'1‘ota| revenue (farm value), price (all raisins):Noncitrus Fruits & Nuts. bWeighted grower price for grapes dried for raisins and for crush, minus grower costs per lb. Cost data available through 1985 only (French and Nuckton, Ag Econometric AnalEis of the California Raisin lndustg). 12 Table 4. Short Versus Large Almond Crops and Comparison of Revenue and Price ‘ Year Crop Short Difference Prod. as Pet. of Total Average Annual Price as Size‘ versus Between Prod. Previous 4 Years Revenue Annual a Percentage of ‘ (mil. Large and Previous 4 Average (mil. 3) Grower Previous 4 Years . lbs.) Crop Years Average Shipments Price Average Price 1 Shipments (mil.lbs.) ($/lb.) 1 1965 79.1 45.0 0.57 1966 95.0 51.9 054 1967 82.2 44.6 054 1968 80.6 < 1 100 44.5 055 1969 1323 large 50 160 73.9 0.56 102 1970 148.4 large 55 159 80.1 0.54 98 1971 160.7 large 54 151 87.1 0.54 98 II 1972 150.1 23 118 98.1 0.65 119 II ‘ 1973 154.7 13 109 200.0 1.29 226 1974 229.3 large 85 158 170.1 0.74 98 1975 185.6 35 123 128.0 0.68 80 1976 283.8 large 125 179 184.0 0.65 78 1977 313.1 large 130 171 264.5 0.84 102 1978 181.0 short -36 83 262.5 1.45 202 1979 376.0 large 144 162 579.0 154 171 1980 321.8 62 124 473.3 1.47 131 1981 407.4 large 138 151 2995 0.78 59 1982 346.7 large 62 122 311.1 0.94 72 1983 241.9 short -64 79 231.9 1.04 88 1984 586.9 large 284 194 446.1 0.77 73 1985 464.7 large 133 140 360.6 0.8 91 1986 251.6 short -120 68 461.6 1.92 216 1987 659.7 large 289 178 648.0 1.00 88 1988 590.0 large 173 142 600.1 1.05 ' 94 1989 4885 40 109 480.9 1.02 86 1990 656.2 large 198 143 598.0 0.93 75 1991 485.9 ~30 94 564.2 1.19 114 ‘Crop size, total revenue and price data from “Almond Statistics" (Almond Board of California) and Noncitrus Fruits and Nuts (NASS. USDA). Total revenue is farm value. Net revenue is not computed due to lack of cost data. indicatl criteria period levels [I represe. Exceplic for the; Were big bad bee Ci"T‘npart of strong “a” in 12 were are Prior 101 P ”be [E’Ve .itif‘x Price Pug-Um: 13 indicated in the last column of Table 3. Large almond crops are defined by the same criterion, ranged from 122% to 190% of prior four-year average shipments, during the period 1965-1992. During the 19808, crops of that magnitude were associated with price levels that ranged between 59% and 98% of prior four-year average prices. These criteria, based on comparisons of production to prior average shipments, represent only an approximate means to define large and short crops, because there are exceptions in each case. For example, 1977 tart cherry production was 121% of shipments for the previous four years, but should not characterized as a large crop year because prices were high enough to yield positive net revenue for typical growers. The previous year’s crop had been quite short (61% of the previous four years’ shipments). The percentage comparison also needs to be viewed with caution for raisins. The late 19708 was a period of strong raisin export demand, so that prices were 123%-140% of prior four-year averages even in large crop years (as defined by the 120% of prior four year shipments criterion) and were even higher in short crop years. With almonds, large crops by the 140% definition prior to the 1980s were not associated with low prices (e.g., price levels substantially below price levels in the prior four years). Thus the percentage comparisons provide one useful general indication of what represents large and short crops, but the comparisons should be made with caution. It would have been preferable to establish net revenue as the main criterion for assessing what are large and small crops, but sufficient data were not available to do so. Crop size has a significant impact on price fluctuation. When large tart cherry crops occurred, prices in those years were 83% or less of the average prices for the previous four years. Prices ranged as low as 36% (1982) and 27% (1987) of the previous four-year average, as shown in the second to the last column of Table 2. Also, in most large crop years, prices ranged from under one cent to seventeen cents below estimated average cost of production, as shown in the last column in Table 2. L8 as they ha have been Slings hal ctplanatio inelastic a $83181 me T31 Years than 17% for t; 14 Large crops have not had as strong a downward price effect with almonds and raisins as they have had with tart cherries. For raisins, the magnitude of the supply fluctuations have been proportionally smaller than for cherries. The magnitude of year-to-year supply swings have in a number of cases been larger than for almonds than for cherries, so the explanation of less price variability lies both in the fact that almonds are not as price inelastic and because certain marketing institutions (federal marketing orders) provide greater means to mitigate the impact of large supplies. Tart cherries have had more severe annual supply fluctuations during the last 25 years than have almonds or raisins. Average annual percentage changes in production were 17% for tart cherries, 15% for almonds, and 10% for raisins for the period 1965-1992. Production variability for these three crops is compared to other perennial crops in Table 5. Additional measures of variability include INS and the coefficient of variation.3 Tart cherries rank as the most variable perennial crop by two of the three measures for the period 1965-1992. The high CV for almonds for 1965-1992 (0.59) is because mean production in the denominator of the CV calculation was low. Considering the more recent period 1981-1990, it is evident that almond production variability has increased substantially and appears to have become more variable than tart cherries when measured by INS or CV. However, the figures in Table 1 indicate that tart cherries have a more serious production variability problem in terms of frequency of short crops when considering the period 1967-1990. On the other hand, there has been only one short tart cherry crop since 1983 because tart cherries have been in a period of excessive plantings. 3INS is an index measure of variability or instability known as the variance of annual percentage change. See Ian Dalziell, ”Sources of Agricultural Marketing Instability," Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State University, 1985. The coefficient of variation is the standard deviation divided by the mean. 15 Table 5. Production Variability Measures For Selected Perennial Crops 1965-1992 1981-1992 Average Coeffi- Average Coeffi- Annual cient of Annual cient of Percentage Vari- Percentage Vari- Changel ation2 INS3 Change ation INS Tart Cherries 16.6 0.26 1674 19.4 0.26 2123 Almonds 14.3 0.59 1442 18.0 0.29 2144 Hazelnuts 15.2 0.42 1420 17.6 0.31 1764 I Raisins 9.3 0.25 664 7.6 0.14 292 [ Plums 6.7 0.20 287 8.6 0.14 435 Sweet Cherries 8.5 0.21 476 75 0.15 412 Freestone 6.8 0.15 312 7.8 0.13 375 Peaches Blueberries‘ 8.1 0.34 386 4.1 0.15 72 Apples 3.9 0.20 104 3.9 0.12 128 l Nectarines 4.7 0.41 133 3.8 0.10 90 1Average annual percentage change is the average of year-to-year percentage changes, which are measured as a percentage of the average production for each pair of adjacent years. 2Coefficient of variation is the standard deviation of production divided by the mean. 3INS is the variance of annual percentage change. This index of variability effectively dctrends a data series. If production increased by a constant proportion each year (e.g., 10% per year), there would be zero variance and consequently INS would equal zero. ‘Blueberry data are through 1990 only. Of the three industries, the tart cherry industry has experienced the largest annual price swings; the coefficient of variation for cherry prices for the period 1964-1989 was .65. The comparable figures for raisin and almond prices were .50 and .41, respectively. The higher price variability for tart cherries was due mainly to the larger relative swings in tart cherry production combined with price inelastic demand. All three commodities exhibit price inelastic demand, as evidenced through price flexibilities (approximately the inverse of demand elasticities). A for tart cl. raisins as evidence . variability Pe Occurs wit overPFOdu growers m m'elpfodu t a Wiser to take a0 the [0m 1] Emerafiyn me 8368. Pitt impact all"re. mils to 16 Analysis in Chapter 6 indicates that grower price flexibilities are approximately -2.0 for tart cherries and -1.4 for almonds. Nuckton and others computed price elasticity of bulk raisins as -0.2, approximately equivalent to a price flexibility of -5.0.‘ Although the evidence suggests that raisin price flexibilities are higher, tart cherries have higher price variability due to larger swings in production. 2.2. Long-Term Supply Trends and Overproduction Periods of overproduction occur in various agricultural subsectors. If overplanting occurs with perennial crops, those subsectors may experience excess production capacity, overproduction and prices below typical grower costs for a number of years. Individual growers make acreage expansion decisions that in the aggregate may result in considerable overproduction capacity for the subsector when the new acreage reaches bearing age. This is a consequence of secondary uncertainty, which arises because growers are often unable to take account of the aggregate consequences of their planting decisions. Growers have limited knowledge of the planting intentions of other growers and of the consequences of the total impact of those planting decisions on future supply and prices. Also, growers generally make planting decisions in the belief that their individual decisions will not affect the aggregate supply. When many growers plant at the same time, as is often the case, the net impact on total productive capacity can be large. Primary uncertainty is due chiefly to supply variability attributable to climatic and biological factors such as those discussed above. For a number of crops the result is similar: periods of high prices typically lead growers to form overly optimistic expectations regarding future profit levels and to plant ‘C.F. Nuckton, B.C. French, and 6C. King, An Econometric Analysis of the CM 321W. Gianninni Foundation Research Report No. 339, University of California, December 1988, 30. The point of means elasticity was computed at the 1983 values. new acr cannot l result in after the the late 17 new acreage to the point where productive capacity is significantly expanded. If demand cannot be expanded by a commensurate amount, these expansionary plantings sometimes result in a level of supply which leads to economic losses by growers for a number of years after the new acreage begins bearing. For example, expansionary tart cherry plantings in the late 19708 resulted in a period of large supplies and low prices beginning in the mid- 19808. As shown in Figure 1 at the beginning of this chapter, tart cherry bearing acres declined steadily after 1964 and leveled out around 1978. Largely in response to high prices in the late 19708, growers made substantial new plantings in the late 19708 and early 19808. Bearing acreage began to rise significantly around 1983, and in the second half of the 19808 serious overproduction problems became evident. (A tart cherry tree is defined as "bearing” in the sixth year after planting.) Though many perennial crops exhibit some type of long-term cycle, it is more pronounced in some crops, such as tart cherries, than in others. The longer-term cyclical production pattern for cherries contrasts with the almond market, which has seen fairly steady long-term growth in both demand and supply (despite large year to year variation). Almond demand expansion has been more effective in keeping up with large increases in production than has tart cherry demand expansion. Almond demand expansion has been facilitated in part by the fact that almonds are relatively inexpensive to store. Due to significant almond production variability, large inventories are sometimes carried over into a subsequent marketing year. The combination of collective storage through a federal marketing order (examined in Chapter 5) and storage by the almond marketing cooperative and other firms helps reduce the likelihood that shortages of supply will subsequently affect demand or that higher prices from short-run fluctuations will send false signals to producers about future price prospects. tl’l—‘llial 811 are also Vegetable This 600. 0(”10:41:15 and (he . milks Wilma. Fear. {of ' 18 Table 6. Number of Years from Planting on Bearing and Typical Life Span for Three Perennial Crops Years from Typical Planting to Economic Life Bearing for Tree/ Vine Tart Cherries 6 20-35 Almonds 5 20-35 Raisin-type Grapes 3 several decades Supply-demand balance problems for perennial crops differ considerably from the typical situation with annual crops, and the typical supply-demand coordination mechanisms are also different for perennials than for annual crops. Markets for annual processing vegetables are coordinated to a large extent by preplanting contracts with prices specified. This coordinating mechanism is rarely used with perennial crops. Annual preplanting contracts for annual vegetables facilitate rapid adjustments to supply-demand imbalances, and the processing firms that provide the contracts with growers typically use market analyses and predictions of market conditions for the upcoming year in determining contracted quantities. If excess production of a certain annual vegetable occurs in a given year, for example, the contracted acreage can be reduced in the following year. In contrast to annual crops, adjustment periods for perennial crop acreage usually last a number of years because of the large fixed investments in bearing acreage, the time lag between planting and bearing, and the long life span of perennial crops. The typical life span for an almond or tart cherry orchard is 20 to 35 years, and for raisin-type grapes, several decades. Downward adjustments made by growers in removing orchards or vineyards in response to low returns due to excess capacity are usually slow. However, when returns have been low for a number of years, substantial acreage may be removed in a telntiveh of cycles remove t of incom income ti lemming enterpris. however, general jl CO“Worth “tilt 50ml because 0 01 other g l“ Orcharc in “Wage Ar gel-3’5 er apflated l 19 relatively short period of time.5 The pattern for cherries illustrates a common occurrence of cycles in production. All optimizing rule in economic theory recommends that an economic decision to remove trees or vines be based on a grower’s estimate that the net present value of a stream of income from a particular block is less than the sum of (a) the net present value of the income that could be obtained from an alternative use of that land minus (b) the cost of removing the trees and the loss in value of assets that cannot be redeployed into alternative enterprises. Knowledgeable extension agents with experience in fruit industries indicate, however, that growers generally do not make such explicit calculations but instead make general judgments using approximate figures. The agents have observed that growers commonly compare current or recent prices to variable and perhaps fixed and total costs with some vague thoughts about the future. The predictions are understandably vague because of the uncertainty that growers face, especially uncertainty relating to the actions of other growers of the same crop. A common result is periods of grower overinvestment in orchards or vines (as well as the associated equipment) and slow downward adjustment in acreage once the excess plantings have occurred. Another factor contributing to long-term oversupply problems is that even if some growers exit from production, their orchards or vines often stay in production, in some cases operated by a new owner who may have purchased the orchard at a loss to the original owner.‘ Overcapacity problems can thus plague a perennial crop industry for many years. Examination of tart cherry acreage trends over the last 40 years (Figure 1) indicates that bearing acreage has risen and fallen two times, suggesting a cyclical pattern. In sLarry Hamm, "Food Distributor Procurement Practices: Their Implications for Food System Structure and Coordination," Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, 1981. 6Dr. Donald Ricks, Dept. of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, Personal communication. 20 contrast, a fairly steady and pronounced long-term upward trend is evident for almonds since the 19608 (Figure 2) with a leveling off since the mid-19808 and a slight downturn in the 19908. Figure 3 indicates that Thompson seedless grape bearing acreage, after remaining fairly steady for many years, rose sharply in the late 19708 and early 19808 and then began to decline in the mid-19808. Thompson seedless grape production represents approximately 90% of all raisin-type grape production. Raisins produced from Thompson seedless grapes are called Natural Thompson Seedless raisins (NTS). The preceding pages have provided a general overview and comparison on the short -run and long-run supply-demand balancing problems for the three commodities. Now the supply-demand balancing problems for each of the three commodities are examined in more detail. 2.3. Tart Cherry Supply-Demand Balancing Problems This section examines both short-run and long-run supply demand balancing problems in the tart cherry subsector. The effect on production and market supplies from the combination of weather-induced annual fluctuations in yields and the longer-run cyclical nature of bearing acreage often sends confusing market signals to growers and processors. For example, it is difficult to determine to what extent high or low cherry prices in a given year are the result of short-run annual supply fluctuations and to what extent the prices reflect the longer-run supply-demand balance related to the cyclical phenomenon. It is especially difficult for growers to interpret where the industry is in terms of productive capacity when the industry is near a turning point in the long-term cycle and then has an unusually short or unusually large crop. Acreage figures which might help growers interpret these trends are published too late and too infrequently (every four years) to serve as an effective guide to decision making. Thus although it is clear that short tart cherry crops in 1990 and 1991 were partially due to weather-induced short-run fluctuations, opinions differed short cr over-cat product some di analfiet demand with sup 21 differed among growers, processors, and other industry participants on whether or not these short crops represent a turning point in the long-run cycle of productive capacity.’ In the long-run cyclical pattern of tart cherry bearing acreage, periods of industry over-capacity and under-capacity are interspersed with periods of approximate balance of productive capacity with demand. The impact on supply and demand, prices and costs of some different periods of the production cycle in the most recent twenty-year period can be analyzed using Figure 4 and Figure 5. The years 1972-1975 were a period of approximate balance between supply and demand at a remunerative price. Price P,, resulting from the intersection of demand D. with supply 8. in Figure 4, represents a price level that is consistent with generally moderate levels of supply. Extending that price level on a dotted line over to Figure 5 is intended to show that the 1972-1975 period was a period in which grower prices approximated average total cost of production (ATC) for typical well-managed grower firms, represented by the flat portion of the ATC curve. The next period in the tart cherry cycle, 1976-1981, can be characterized as a period of general under-capacity of production in relation to potential demand, with frequent short crops and unusually high prices received for cherries. This is shown graphically by the shift from S. to Sb and the rise in the price level to Pb, which is considerably above typical grower cost of production in Figure 5. Growers responded to high prices during this short supply period with substantially increased plantings, resulting first in a transitional period of approximate balance of supply and demand from 1982 to 1984 and then a period of chronic over-capacity during the period 1985-1989. Over-capacity is shown graphically by the supply 7Dr. Donald J. Ricks, personal communication. 4 . .:];E.:.£CJ;:.V >5 VCCIQCCLCQ CCC atOIC-ZCEu EQQJm ODD .aCQ C. Ucoltvu m. 0:02.503 .AQW 0. 0m ECL» .Ziwv ”007.3 £37; UCC MQGC.LOCW 7.03030 C »O 30.80Q .sAZUUQUU O):UJUOtQ C— cozUJUDQ up mlwhm— .UUC5.UD l¢UETXULQQU ‘0 no. spunk ”WK. Aw — l. NR aw n 22 o amm— $3: 88 o>< . .38 $3; on :3. oe< .eaam_v lllllllllllllll Tlllllll 82¢ .38 2.2.";— 833 8.5 8.8.6 5... e. .80 nos—:0 09225. he mincezata .e 9...»:— .m._oo> 03.6132 Co 89:3: 0 ozamme smooth. :25: mo 3:35 .o 5:383 3:523 o 2 one ton c_ 5.30% m_ 530.5 2.250 .8 2 3:5. :33. .mmczcoa >38; 2 one ”ommptmwe 60:23 20E_xo.aao .o totem ”vwmplmmm— .30 o. no Ea... Ecmv 3&3 033.025 can 325 :9: .0 33203358 ecu 98:20.. anm .3 20:39.3 ecu 20:022.: 2&3. one ton c. 3030.. m_ 9.950 .3m 2 cm Ea: :23 82.5 :9; ecu monotocm .5333. .o octan— .>:ooaoo 3:01.095 5 cozosnom "Elana— .ooco_on 2953.230 .0 totem "m N. m T N n m _ mum. Howimmm.v 6m Ana-~8m_ A_m-£m_xm\/ .Bm: 6“. Anna. -Nam_v an. :2: .tmc ea 8:35 853.50 2.3.5 883.3 asweeeo e. 25 mow-3:0 35‘— oo....— 3320 EEO tag. me 5.3.53:— .m 25E shift u C0513] and de tart ch period grower beiow r 23 shift to S, which results in generally low grower prices. Pc in Figure 5 is below grower total cost and variable cost per pound. The preceding graphs illustrate the meaning of long-term imbalance between supply and demand of perennial crops by showing the effects on grower price levels of changes in tart cherry productive capacity at different periods of the production cycle. During the period of declining tart cherry acreage, frequent shortages led to price levels well above grower costs in most years. Subsequent heavy plantings resulted in grower price levels below typical grower costs. It is important to put more precise meaning into this discussion of excess production and shortages with actual price and cost figures. Graphical comparisons of tart cherry prices with cost of production in Figure 6, Figure 7, and Figure 8 help to do this. Michigan tart cherry cost of production data was obtained from cost estimates carried out in 1971, 1979, 1984, and 1989. Total and variable production cost figures at an average yield of 2.6 tons per acre for the four survey years are plotted in Figure 6 with connecting lines to illustrate the cost trends (2.6 tons per acre was the approximate statewide average in recent years). Costs beyond 1989 were increased at a constant rate of 2% per year. The sharp increase in average total cost (ATC) between 1979 and 1984 and the decline between 1984 and 1989 were due largely to changes in the cost of land and orchards, which represents in part the capitalization into land and orchards of the higher expected stream of income resulting from high tart cherry prices in the late 19708 and early 19808. Since ATC is itself influenced by grower prices for tart cherries, comparisons of price and ATC as a measure of imbalance and supply and demand should be done with caution, and greater reliance should be placed on comparing price and variable cost. A production cost time series for the entire period was constructed by interpolating between survey years using the assumption that both variable and total costs changed by equal increments each year. The original cost survey figures were presented as costs per Ton UCJOQ LOQ 9.9.00 hut: Cl kmu Q Ix 9:»er 24 Figure 6. Michigan Tart Cherry Grower Total and Variable Cost with Yield of 2.6 Tons/Acre 70 a 60 a '0 SO - c as. .. L 40 ‘ O a q U! "E 30 a 8 1 Total Cost per Pound 20 a 10 ~ . Variable Cost per Pound q 19'70'19'72'19'74'19'76'19'78'19'8619'82'19’8439’86‘19‘88'19'90: 9'92 Figure 7. Michigan Tart Cherry Grower Prices Compared to Variable and Total Cost at Average Yield Each Year 70 4 197245 1976-81 1982-84 1985-90 Approximaf. Frequent Approx. Persistent ‘ Balance Shortages Balance Overproduction 50'} . L : : # F% 50 r g / ,. o ‘ alt’ a. 40 q l Total Cost 3 per Pound o, a *3 :50 4 8 -i 20 Price ax 3". 10 + ‘3‘. , -i "" Variable Cost per Pound o I I I I I I I I I I I I j 7 I I I I I I 17 I I I I I I I 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 Source: Price data from "Noncitrus Fruits and Nuts. ' ERS/USDA. annual summaries. various years. Cost data: see previous figure. Harri 250( 200C 1500 DOLLARS 1000 500 25 Figure 8. Michigan Tart Cherry Grower Total and Variable Cost and Revenue Per Acre 2500 1 978 2000 a Total Cost per Acre Revenue Per Acre 1500: I ‘ 1000‘ l DOLLARS ‘ l P” V 1987 500« / - Variable Cost per Acre O r r j—T I I I 19'70' 1975 '19'80' ' ' ' 1 '19'35 '19'90' ' acre. The time series per-acre cost figures were then divided by actual annual average yields per acre to give the total and variable costs per pound at average seasonal yields. Harvesting costs were included as the number of cents per pound. The resulting cost figures were plotted with bold lines to form the ”cost band” in Figure 7. Figure 7 compares grower prices to grower cost per pound. Annual average Michigan grower prices for processing were plotted on the same graph with each year’s price appearing as an asterisk. Michigan prices are typically about equal to U.S. prices since Michigan produces over 70% of U.S. tart cherries. Thus comparison of Michigan price and cost of production is a reasonable approximation for the entire U.S. Figure 8 compares grower returns per acre (gross revenue) to cost per acre. Costs per acre are computed by taking the cost survey figures (which were per-acre figures) and adding costs that were given in cents per pound (multiplied by average yields per acre). Both relative to pr such as in 19 total cost of j 0i productio Ol’erproductit Variable cost Comp Production (b. Cherry Sales v.- “idence of ex incentive pmg Compa helps illustrate 0‘3ng PiOdu by a it‘l'ear m0 image of the Wmmmm quantiu'eS of [a 26 Both Figure 7 and Figure 8 indicate that when short crops occur, prices are high relative to preceding or succeeding years and are often well above total cost of production, such as in 1977-1979. In large crop years such as 1975 and 1980, prices tend to drop below total cost of production of a typical grower. When prices are consistently below total cost of production, such as from 1985 through 1989, this provides evidence of persistent overproduction. In the very large crop year of 1987, gross revenue per acre was below variable cost of production. Comparisons of production and sales forecasts showed that estimated average production (based on a 1990 orchard survey) is likely to exceed projected processed tart cherry sales well into the 19905.8 The orchard survey and related analysis provided some evidence of excess tart cherry productive capacity upon which plans for an orchard removal incentive program were developed. Orchard removal issues are examined in Chapter 5. Comparing average tart cherry production with average quantity sold in Figure 9 helps illustrate the problem that supply shortages tend to constrain long-run demand growth. Average production (plotted as bars in Figure 9) is computed by multiplying bearing acreage by a 4-year moving average of yields. Potential average annual sales are computed as the average of the two highest years out of the previous four, based on the assumption that annual sales could have stayed at the highest levels attained in recent years had sufficient quantities of tart cherries been produced to meet that demand. Four year periods were selected as the most accurate means of estimating averages due to the improved averaging effect of having two high production and two low production years. Tart cherry sales are defined as equivalent to processed movement, which is computed as beginning inventory plus pack minus ending inventory. The tart cherry pack is the quantity processed as frozen, pie filling, and canned. . “Cherry Marketing Institute, ”Report on Michigan Tart Cherry Survey," Okemos, MlChigan, 18 January 1991. lbs.) Prod. and Sales (mill. 27 Figure 9. Average U.S. Tart Cherry Production, Average Sales, and Bearing Acreage 500 60 1972-75 1976—81 1982-84 1985-90 450 * Approx. Frequent Approx. Persistent r Shortages Balance Overproduction r) 400 ~ -50 :3 Potential =. 350 ‘ Average Sales ' A "’ U) \E/ 300 " -40 8 a . Average Production 0 g 250 - ; - c m m "g 200 - e L:50 8 . _ o O I Z < 15 150 ‘ i :j - O z h . . 0- 100 J i'20 so - t ° . . 10 7b r7h 7k '7k 75 3b 'ai 'a4rah '8a '9b Crop Year The resulting graph in Figure 9 is consistent with Figure 7 in that the same cyclical periods are also evident though less pronounced. One can observe during the period 1976- 81 that the reduced productive capacity from declining acreage resulted in average production generally below potential demand (average annual sales). Although average production is equal to average sales in 1977, one should note the pattern over several years rather than in one particular year. The general downward trend of average annual sales from 1976 to 1980 provides some evidence that one key impact of shortages during that period was dampened demand. When acreage and production began to rise around 1982, demand growth lagged behind. The preceding discussion focused on the long-run cyclical aspect of tart cherry supply instability. The focus now turns to annual supply fluctuations. Supply instability combined with inadequate storage is a major aspect of the problem of balancing subsector supply and demand on an annual basis. Figure 10 illustrates the annual supply fluctuation problem by 28 presenting Mal sales and 16.1%! production rather than moving averages as in Figure 9. The problem of frequent shortages is evident. There were ten years with short crops between 1966 and 1991 as defined by the criterion in Table 2. The short crop years were: 1966, 1967, 1973, 1976, 1978, 1979, 1981, 1983, 1990, and 1991. A key occurrence in each of these short crop years was that total sales dropped off sharply due to the reduced supplies. Another key factor is that because of the risks associated with storage by individual firms, during most years there is generally little processed product stored to meet the short crop possibilities. Some alternative coordination mechanisms for dealing with this problem are examined in Chapter 5. However, some stabilization through storage did occur during the years of general excess capacity in the late 19808. Although tart cherry processors have generally tried to Figure 10. U.S. Total Tart Cherry Production and Total Sales, 1950-1991 ’10; 350 ‘ g . Production , Sales 8. 300 ~ c - =2 :5] 250 " . 1 m ‘ I I r 3 200 ‘ . . < . m l l g 150 - 4 . ‘. E, 100 ~ .— 8 .. 8 50 ‘ a: . a. o .J 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 Crop Year 29 have as little carryover as possible, the prevalence of large crops during that period meant that some processed product was stored because of the difficulty of selling the larger quantities in commercial channels. Note that the graph in Figure 10 shows that production levels in 1986 and 1988 were well below sales. Although at first glance those graphs appear to indicate that shortages could have a negative impact on demand (because of the gap between production and sales) this was not the case. In both of those years, there were large carryin stocks due to heavy production in 1985 and 1987. In addition, production levels were approximately 111% and 101%, respectively, of the average of prior years’ shipments. Thus sales did not decline, largely due to the stabilizing effect of stored cherries. However, tart cherry industry observers have noted that although large stocks in those years did have a stabilizing effect, most interseasonal storage is unplanned storage. The large size of cherry carryover stocks in those years was largely due to handler inability to sell large additional quantities. Industry observers caution that storage by processing firms will generally not be adequate to mitigate the problems caused by supply volatility, including the lack of product in short crop years. Further evidence that 1986 and 1988 did not represent shortage years is that in 1986 and 1988 average grower prices were on average about 14¢ per pound and 7c per pound lower than total grower costs (see Figure 7). Although bearing acreage changes little from one year to the next, production continues to be subject to wide annual fluctuations throughout various phases of the tart cherry production cycle. Wide fluctuations in prices were especially noteworthy during certain time periods such as the 19703 and early 1980s, when large year-to-year changes in production were particularly frequent. Large production in a given year can push grower prices below annual variable costs, causing severe economic hardships. The 1987 national tart cherry crop was very large and Michigan grower prices averaged approximately 8c per pound, which was 3c less than annual variah pounc deuce a hug Short 2 IEgardi Pattern POUndS the Ear} alfigh l 7L ““533: Figure 30 variable costs of growing and harvesting for a typical grower and 17¢ less than total cost per pound (see Figure 7). Since cherry demand is price inelastic, especially at the farm level, even large decreases in grower price result in only small increases in the quantities of cherries sold in a large crop year. Significant demand expansion is not easily achieved within a period as short as one year. Due in part to the problems encountered in trying to stabilize markets through storage by individual firms, a tart cherry federal marketing order supply management program was established to facilitate storage on a collective basis. The coordination role played by marketing orders is examined in Chapter 5. 2.4. Almond Supply-Demand Balancing Problems In contrast to tart cherries during the last 25 years, the longer-run almond situation regarding acreage and production has not been cyclical but rather has shown a sustaining pattern of long-term expansion. Production rose from an average of less than 100 million pounds annually during the mid-19605 to an average in the 500-600 million pound range by the early 19908. Bearing acreage reached a peak in the early 1990s and then continued on a high plateau with a slight decline. The question of whether periods of overcapacity occur in the almond subsector is illustrated graphically by comparing average production and average annual sales in Figure 11.’ It is useful to compare 1972-1979 with the period beginning in 1980. The period 1972-1979 was selected for comparison because the seventies were years of strong almond demand in which the almond marketing order was not used. Prior to 1972 and after 1980 the almond marketing order was regularly used in large crop years. ’Average production (plotted as bars) is calculated by multiplying the three year moving average of yields by bearing acreage. A three-year moving average of delivered sales is plotted on the same graph. Sltuam 31 Figure 11. U.S. Average Almond Production and Average Sales 800 450 \l O O 1_ 0’ O O Average Production . . Bearing Acres . I ; 1 I I s ....... 0| 0 O O ........ OOOOOOOOOOO 04 O O 000000000000 0000000000000 Prod. and Sale: (mm. lbs.) .5; o o OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO Crop Year During the period 1972-1979, the bar graph representing average production in Figure 11 and the line graph representing average sales are about the same height, indicating approximate equality of production and sales and thus an approximate balance of supply (productive capacity) and demand. Even though bearing acreage was increasing steadily, oversupply in the U.S. market was not a big problem because increasing quantities of almonds were exported as can be seen in Figure 12. U.S. sales rose and fell and then rose again during that period, but the overall sales had a gradual upward trend. The situation changed in the early 1980s, however, when production capacity began to rise sharply due to improved yields and rising acreage.lo Generally weaker economic conditions in much of the world led to faltering export sales in the early 19808. Almond exports began to rise again in the mid-1980s, but a very short crop in 1986 substantially disrupted the pattern of increasing export sales (this is examined in more detail below). l"Average yields rose from 850-880 pounds per acre in the late 1970s to over 1000 pounds in the early 1980s (measured as three year annual averages). 32 Figure 12. Domestic and Export Almond Sales, 1964-1991 400 04 (N O U! 0 O l l N 0| 0 Export Sales 100 4 Domestic Sales Domestic and Export Sales (1000 tons) a. a: '5’ o o o I I III rfI I I I I I I I I I I I I I 0 64 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 Crop Year The net result of these factors was a period of overcapacity in the 1980s. From 1980 on, the bar graphs in Figure 11 representing production are generally above the line representing average sales, providing one indication of general overcapacity. Production above sales levels was either stored as carryover stocks or disposed of in alternative sales outlets that did not compete with sales in the primary commercial channels. In some years this was accomplished through the operation of the federal marketing order reserve, which is explained in Chapter 5. The fact that there were many years of large supplies is also evident from examining the graph in Figure 13 which compares actual annual delivered sales (versus a moving average of sales in the previous graph) and total U.S. production of almonds. Production levels in 1984, 1987, 1988 and 1990 were particularly large relative to sales and production and levels in prior years. One would expect large crops such as these to result in prices below cost of production, as was shown to be the case with tart cherries. However, because of a lack of \J O O __..__L__.{ (II 0‘! O O O 0 Jul :5 O O N O O PRODUCTION AND SALES (million lbs.) 5 "c’; o O ‘J‘J‘Aw—J. _._L_.__—L—_ 33 Figure 13. U.S. Almond Production and Total Sales 700 Production 400 'l 300 ‘ Soles \ 200 - °°‘ I [I I | DJ I II I l 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 Crop Year 1 01 O O l l U" C O l l J J l PRODUCTION AND SALES (million lbs.) 1 data, a meaningful price-cost comparison across time could not be made for alrnonds. Part of the difficulty in developing time series data for costs is that production costs are highly variable across production zones because of differing land ownership or tenancy relationships among growers and because of other factors. The magnitude of annual swings in almond production has increased along with the average level of production. Table 5 in section 2.1 shows that average annual percentage change for almonds was 14.3% for the period 1965-1992, but had increased to 18.0% for the period 1981-1992. Figure 13 also shows that short crops (well below sales) were particularly evident in 1978, 1983, and 1986.11 The situation was somewhat different for 1989 and 1991, as will be discussed below. In 1986, the general unavailability of almonds and record high almond 11Production in those years was 83%, 79%, and 68%, of average sales for the previous four years. 34 prices ($1.92 per pound versus prices ranging from $0.77 to $1.04 for the three preceding years) resulted in a loss of sales outlets that hampered subsequent demand grth when production levels later rose to substantially higher levels.12 The question arises as to whether the shifts in quantities sold from year to year with the variation in supplies represent shifts in demand or movement along a fixed demand curve. The evidence suggests both. The graphs indicate that when production increases in year after a short crop, sales generally recover to levels somewhere near previous years of comparable production levels, which suggest that only movement along a demand curve has taken place. The evidence that the demand curve has also shifted in more anecdotal. Interviews with handlers revealed that sales of certain types of manufacturer buyers will cease buying in response to the unavailability, at least for several years, suggesting that preferences have changed--the manufacturers change their product offering to consumers to food products with a more reliable supply. This situation is similar to the dampening of demand associated with the tart cherry shortage period in the 1970s and in 1981 and 1983, in which the reduced supply and higher prices contributed to a decline in demand. The juxtaposition of the very short crop year in 1986 and two large crop years (1987 and 1988) led to a significant policy change regarding the operation of the almond reserve under the federal marketing order. Subsequent to 1986, almond reserves were used increasingly as a means for collective industrywide storage to reduce the likelihood of shortages as occurred in 1986. Referring again to Figure 13, it is evident that a stabilizing effect did occur in 1989 and 1991 since sales did not drop off as had occurred during previous short crops. This was due to storage of almonds both through the almond marketing order reserve and through storage by individual handlers. Supply management through federal marketing orders and other means is covered in Chapter 5. 1“Blue Diamond Growers, Inc., ”Annual Report 1987-1988.” Price data from "Statistical Tables,” Almond Board of California, various years. com sum 3UP. Whel Slead and v addiu' subs. 35 2.5. Raisin Supply-Demand Balancing Problems A key factor that differentiates the raisin supply situation from that of the other two commodities is that shifts in market utilization of grapes in a given year affect the raisin supply. The raisin supply depends not only on the amount of raisin variety grape bearing acreage and yields but also on market utilization decisions by growers. Growers decide whether to dry the grapes for raisins or to sell them in one of three alternative market outlets: (a) crush (winemaking), (b) fresh (table grapes), or (c) canning. Since the proportion of the crop used fresh and for canning has remained relatively constant at 12- 15%, the grower decision that has the greatest effect on the annual raisin supply is between drying grapes for raisins or selling them for crushing into grape juice for wine-making. Growers switch back and forth between the crush market and the raisin market based on expected relative returns and the availability of the crush market in a given year. Figure 14 shows that although the overall level of raisin-type grape acreage has been steady for many years (up until the early 19805), grower decisions to shift between the raisin and wine markets has caused acreage harvested for raisins to vary considerably.13 This additional factor of uncertainty and supply volatility contributed to the difficulty of balancing subsector supply and demand. Weather has also played a role in raisin production variability. Frost damage in 1972 and post-harvest rain damage in 1976 and 1978 affected the crop on a substantial proportion of the Thompson grape acreage as shown by the decline in acreage for those years in Figure 15 for ”N18 Raisin Harvested Acres.” The reason that acreage declines in years of 1"The data series for the graph of "Acres Harvested for Raisins” in Figure 14 was computed by multiplying total raisin-type grape bearing acreage time the percentage of grapes dried into raisins. The graph is intended only to demonstrate that changes in market utilization have a considerable impact on raisin production (the line representing production in the graph is raisin production, not production of raisin-type grapes). It should be viewed only as an illustration of utilization changes from year to year over the time period shown and not as a precise measure of acreage harvested for raisins in any given year. PRODUCTION (1000 tons) 36 Figure 14. Raisin We Grape Bearing Acreage and Acreage Harvested for Raisins 300 500 ‘ 450 4 Raisin Variety Grape Bearing Acres ‘ ”250 I”? 400 ‘ g 4 Temporary Non-production of Acres _ A "' 350 ‘ through Marketing Order .3 ° ‘ ~2oo S 8 300 - S v- . Production 0 v l- .C 2 250 - :3 9 ‘ tn $53 200 q “‘50 3: a - _ 2 a: 150 a Q_ - 100 ‘ ~100 50: Acres Harvested for Raisins _ 0 T I I I I I r I I I I I I I I n I I I I I I I I I I SO 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 Crop Year extreme weather is that significant portions of grape acreage typically destined for the raisin market are diverted to other uses (such as alcohol distillation) during those years because the grapes on those acres are damaged. However, it is evident that even without weather extremes in those three years, raisin grape acreage varied considerably from year to year. The "normal weather acres” represented by the dotted lines in Figure 15 are an estimate of what acreage would have been had there been normal weather conditions in 1972, 1976, and 1978. The "normal weather" acreage data points for those three years were computed by averaging the bearing acres before and after the low production years in question. The purpose of doing this is to show that considering the whole period from 1966 to 1991, acres harvested for raisins varied considerably from year to year even without weather extremes. 37 Figure 15. Harvested Acres, Average Production and Average Sales for NTS Raisins 800 _ 1 80 750 .. 1983: Lcrge acreage increase (due to decline NTS Raisin r- in Thompson gape: used in wine ”0""3l’d [170 700 ‘ Acres» : 1 60 650' :150 500 .1972. 1976. 1978: Adverse weather: Dotted lines :140 represent estimated normal weather acres -1 30 550- \ , .......... ”120 500‘ \ :110 A (I) r: o eh o 0 ° 1: C o d ' " O 3 450 AAvergge Production” :100 o a CfOS lmOS OVOVO IO "' 8 400 ...... 9" :90 v 'o 350 - ~ . -30 3 I: : _ ; ” g u 300 s _ 3. _ . . :70 2 c -° : ° .° -.° _ :9; 250 . . Average So as I I I . 3 9 : I I Pg?) 3 200 ‘ e t e e e e e e e e e e e e e .. '3 q I ‘2 I I I l I I I I 3 :40 L 150 O 0 O O 0 0 0 O O O O O O 0 -30 m 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O P 100 ‘ I ‘2 I 2 I I I I I I I 3 ~20 soggggs 2222222 -1o o I I I I I I T T 0 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 Crop Year 2.5.1. [nag-Run Raisin Supply-Demand Balance Issues Turning to long-run issues, the first step is examining trends in overall productive capacity for raisins. Figure 14 indicates that for a number of years from the 1960s until around 1980, raisin variety grape bearing acreage remained relatively steady. However, in the early 1980s the rise in raisin-type grape bearing acreage was due in part to grape grower expectations that they could take advantage of the strong wine market to sell greater quantities of raisin-type grapes for crush.“ Thompson seedless grape juice had traditionally been an important ingredient in California wines. However, various factors altered the situation to the detriment of raisin growers. The booming California wine business in the late 1970s also brought about substantial planting of varietal wine grapes, much of which directly competed with Thompson grapes for blending in generic wines. San “Nuckton and others. WWW 38 Joaquin Valley bearing wine grape acreage doubled during the 19705. Also, a California law was passed in 1983 increasing the proportion of juice from varietal grapes in each bottle labeled with a particular variety, thereby reducing the proportion of Thompson grape juice. California wine sales began to slacken in the 19805 and the high value of the dollar in relation to a number of other currencies encouraged wine imports. Due to the sharp reduction in the quantities of grapes accepted into the traditional crush market outlet, Thompson seedless grape growers substantially increased raisin production in the early 1980s.” This turn of events is depicted graphically in Figure 16, which compares the tonnage of Thompson seedless grapes dried for raisins and tonnage used in other outlets. In the years just prior to 1983, the percentage dried for raisins was 50-60%, with about 30% of the grape tonnage crushed for wine. However, in 1984 the percentage used for wine dropped to 14% and the percentage dried for raisins jumped to 74%. Figure 15 helps to clarify further the issue of overproduction and shortages by comparing average raisin production with average sales (a three year moving average). Average production is computed by multiplying bearing acres times a three year moving average of yields. The graph indicates that a significant amount of acreage did not produce raisins due to weather factors in 1972, 1976, and 1978. These weather-induced short crops appear to have somewhat offset a general trend to overproduction beginning in the mid- 1970s. The graph also shows that grape acreage harvested for raisins increased sharply in 1983 (148% of the previous year’s acreage) due to the aforementioned large-scale shift from crush to raisins by many grape growers. This sharp increase in raisin supply meant a sudden severe imbalance between supply and demand, resulting in a large drop in average grower price from $1153/ton in 1982 to l”Nuckton and others, t ' al s's oft e ' omia Rais' dust 1-2. Quami Fresh Tons (Thousands) N C) (3 3 39 Figure 16. Percentage of Raisin Type Grapes Dried for Raisins and Comparison of Quantity of Grapes Dried for Raisins versus Quantity in All Other Uses, 1966-91 4000 100 ' 19794932: Percentage Percentage dried for raisins h 3500 ~ dried for raisins ls so-soz. lumps '0 747° in 1983 as '90 percentage used for wine percentage used for wine - ‘ averages 30%. drops to 14%. ’80 A3000" / .- 3 ' '70 §2500s * :9: ‘ Percent Dried ~60 + l— for Raisins * g v2000‘ary. _50 r; g .Dried _ a t a "' 1500-2657,.s : 3 5 _40 '5 : .2 : 8 ‘ ‘ E . as s 22:: 2 ~30 “1000‘ ii: ;:5:555:55335 E ’ -Ii.’i:"iiii.iiiiiiii. E '20 5°°‘3.'.’.‘..'." iiiiééiliiééiéiiéé 1,0 _ _ ::.::.,.:::.::::::se::e,:: -0 66 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 Crop Year $587/ton in 1983. This was the beginning of a period of over-capacity, as evidenced by the comparison of price and average cost of production in Figure 17.“ Thus interdependence with the wine market was a major factor contributing to raisin oversupply problems in the 1980s. The downturn in the wine market resulted in sharp increases in raisin market supplies beginning in 1983. This was because a number of growers who had historically sold gapes for crushing shifted more heavily into raisin production. These circumstances brought about several responses by raisin industry organizations, one of which involved “The price series used was the average annual price for all raisin varieties (W Emjg and hints, NASS, USDA). Production cost for NTS raisins is based on multiplying wine varietal grape cost of production by 1.09 (to account for extra costs of drying and handling) and converting to nominal terms by multiplying by the GNP price deflator and the drying ratio to make gape costs equivalent to dried raisin costs. Comparing the price of all raisin varieties to the cost of a single variety (NTS) is a reasonable approximation since NTS production represents 90% of all raisin production. Cost figures were obtained from Nuckton and French, MW 73 40 Figure 17. Comparison of California Raisin Grower Price and Production Cost 1500 ‘ 1400: 1982 Price=$1153 1300 . \7’ 12003 1100 ~ 1000; 900: 800: 700 . 5001 5003 4003 300: 200: 100: Dollars per Ton Production Cost 1983 ”£64587 I I I I I I I I T I I I I I I I I I I I I I I O r v r 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 establishing a progam to encourage gowers to discontinue production temporarily by trimming vines or to remove acreage from production permanently under the Raisin Diversion Progam (RDP). The sharp shifts in bearing acreage beginning in 1984 shown by the dotted lines in Figure 14 are due to implementation of the RDP through the federal marketing order. Producing acreage declined for three successive years, although most of that acreage was removed from production only temporarily. The dotted lines in Figure 14 indicate the number of acres that were removed from production in specific years. Fewer acres were removed under the RDP after 1986 because the supply-demand balance began improving. The RDP is explained in more detail in Chapter 5. Figure 18 also shows year to year variations in the difference between production and sales, with results similar to tart cherries and almonds. The gaph shows that there were five years between 1964 and 1990 with production well below the level of sales of previous years, but in only three of those years did sales decrease significantly due to the shortages: 41 Figure 18. U.S. Total Raisin Production and Total Sales, 1964-1991 400 q 350 a Production 200 4 Sales 150 s 100 d o .r 66 68 7O 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 Crop Year N ()4 UT 0 o O 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Production and Sales (1000 tons) U! C l l 1972, 1976, 1978. Thus, one factor that the raisin market has in common with the markets for almonds and tart cherries is the potential for reduced demand due to shortages. As with almonds, the changes in sales levels appear to reflect both movement along the demand curve and a shift in demand. In the years following shortages, raisin sales recover to levels somewhere near where they were in years prior to the shortage. However, it takes several years to recover to levels fully consistent with prior sales trends, indicating that an inward shift in the demand curve has taken place, followed in many instances by renewed promotional efforts to shift the demand curve outward. However, of the three commodities, the problems of potential shortages are the least serious with raisins. As with the other crops, the question should be posed as to whether interseasonal storage by raisin firms could mitigate the potential problem of annual supply variability. The answer appears to be no, since the irregular pattern of shortages makes it unlikely that individual firms could anticipate the changes in production well enough to store sufficient 42 quantities to avoid a shortage. To deal with this problem, an industry-wide storage progam has been organized through a federal marketing order. The industry as a whole is not necessarily any better at forecasting shortages than are individual entrepreneurs. However, collective storage through a marketing order facilitates sharing the costs of storing sufficient quantities to mitigate the problems caused by shortages. Federal marketing order supply management progams are examined in Chapter 5. 2.6. Concluding Comments In summary, the three perennial crop industries examined in this research face some common problems, including annual supply fluctuations and the long-term challenge of balancing industry productive capacity with potential demand. Of the three crops, cherries and almonds have experienced the largest year-to-year variations in production and raisins the least variation over the period of study (1965-1992). The three industries also differ in the degee of price variability, with cherry prices being the most variable. The raisin industry faces a challenge which has no parallel in the other two industries: volatility in raisin production partially due to multiple uses for raisin variety gapes and the resulting interdependence with the wine industry. CHAPTER 3: THE SUBSECTOR FRAMEWORK AND A CLASSIFICATION OF ORGANIZATIONAL RESPONSES TO COORDINATION PROBLEMS FOR THE THREE PERENNIAL CROPS This chapter introduces the subsector framework used to examine the means to respond to the supply-demand balancing problems introduced in the previous chapter. The subsector framework is used to examine marketing problems related to vertical coordination performance. In addition, a major purpose of this chapter is to introduce a system of classifying certain key coordination actions that have been adopted or considered in perennial crop subsectors. To accomplish this, a means of classifying cooperatives is introduced to help explain potential differences in the contribution that types of cooperatives can make to balancing supply and demand for a commodity. 3.1 The Subsector Framework A useful component in examining the problems of supply-demand balancing is to view an agicultural commodity production and marketing system as a commodity subsector. A subsector consists of a series of stages from the gower to the final consumer stage.l7 Table 7. Vertical Stages in Agricultural Subsectors Stage 1. Growers Stage 2. Initial Processors/ Handlers Stage 3. Food Manufacturers Stage 4. Retailer-Wholesalers Stage 5. Consumers k l7Bruce Marion. jIhe 9122211112. tion and Performance of the 9.8. Eood System, Lexington: D.C. Heath and Company, 1986. Input supply is also generally considered to be a stage in the subsector, but is not included here because input supply is beyond the scope of this analysis. 43 ——l An example I Table 7. The s prices, contra. marketing cc organizations. This a1 (We 1 and . l'tnically linke or IOFs”) are I0 consumer to chmYSUbsecto Figure ; 00mlllOdllies flC m Ploducz lo throngh a COOp booming 1 gm Dimming Or ha 44 An example of an agicultural subsector with five vertically linked stages is presented in Table 7. The stages are linked by a number of vertical coordination mechanisms including prices, contracts, verbal ageements, and various institutional arrangements, including marketing cooperatives, marketing orders, and generic commodity promotional organizations. This analysis focuses largely on the gower and initial processor/handler stages (stages 1 and 2 in Table 7) and their approaches to supply-demand balancing within the vertically linked marketing system. Growers and initial processors/ handlers (cooperative or lOFs“) are collectively referred to as the "industry.” The vertical stages from gower to consumer for each commodity are hereafter referred to as the almond, raisin, and tart cherry subsectors. Figure 19 shows typical major marketing channels through which perennial crop commodities flow. For a processed commodity, marketing alternatives for gowers selling raw product to firms in the initial processor/handler level (stage 2) include: (a) selling through a cooperative, (b) vertically integating downstream as an individual firm by becoming a gower-processor, or (c) selling to investor-owned firms that engage in processing or handling. This research is primarily concerned with first of these three, that is, the role of marketing cooperatives in the vertical system. Some Stage 2 firms are primarily commodity processors and typically sell a portion of their processed tonnage to food manufacturers for industrial use as an ingedient. Other cooperatives and IOFs process and sell a significant portion of gower deliveries as branded retail food products. In such cases where a firm is both initial processor and manufacturer, two or more subsector stages are vertically integated within the firm. For example, a large c00perative that markets a portion of its tonnage as brand-name manufactured products to mIOF = investor-owned firm, as distinguished from a cooperative, which is a patron- owhed firm. 45 Figure 19. Simplified Overview of Main Marketing Channels in Processed Perennial Crop Subsectors Grower Production i Maketing Cooperatives hltid Processors/Hmdlers: lOt's Grower- Processors /, Food Marufactu'ers ‘ 1x Firms Food Service Grocery Retail- Wholesalers Export \/ Consuners retailers can be characterized as vertically integated between the initial processing and food Stage 1 Stage 2 Stage 3 Stage 4 Stage 5 manufacturing stages for the branded portion of its total tonnage marketed. Food manufacturers and initial processors/ handlers may sell in one or more of three main market channels (Stage 4 of Figure 19): (1) food service wholesalers and retailers, (2) gocery retailer-wholesalers, and (3) export. Brokers and other specialized marketing firms can play major roles at various stages of distribution, but such firms were excluded from Figure 19 to simplify the presentation. This framework provides a means to examine problems related to pricing and vertical coordination focusing on the standard operating procedures of retailers and food manufacturers. manufacturers. example of a r pie filling. Th supply and do “try 1: level with the acOmmodiry. ”‘5 dillinstre; ”We“. do ; concerned abc Space for a pa Particular {00c generally have Pmducing {00d regarding the o plot'ldlnga fella! 46 3.2. The Price System and Vertical Coordination Much of the value of the coordination mechanisms that are the focus of this research is their role in facilitating and complementing the coordinating role of prices. The effect on coordination of the standard operating procedures (SOPs) of retailers and food manufacturers, particularly as they relate to pricing, is explained in this section through the example of a representative commodity-based consumer food product, canned tart cherry pie filling. The purpose will be to show that certain pricing SOPs can hinder the flow of supply and demand information through the vertical marketing system. Why is there in some cases incomplete coordination of supply changes at the farm level with the manufacturer stage and retailer stage? Coordinating supply and demand for a commodity and its various related retail products is complicated by the fact that firms in the downstream stages of a commodity subsector, including food manufacturers and retailers, do not have a crop-commodity focus. Retailers have little incentive to be concerned about conditions in a particular subsector. In deciding whether to provide shelf space for a particular product, retailers compare the potential profitability of carrying a particular food product with a set of alternative products. Raw product supply changes generally have generally little impact on key retail decisions. Manufacturers focus on producing food products lines targeted at various market segnents, and their chief concern regarding the commodity is to have a reliable supply. In the view of manufacturers, providing a reliable supply is the function of gowers and initial processors. The business practices and strategies of retail and manufacturing firms can frequently hinder the transmission of market information on supply and demand in a commodity subsector. An example of this problem is related to the common retail practice of “pricing on the nines," in which typical prices charged per pound or per item are, for example, $1.19, $1.29, $1.39 and so on. This practice is based on the observation that for certain gocery products, consumers tend not to appreciably alter purchased amounts over amgup behavioral ten grocery retail the cost of too be reflected at This '11 lilting on th difierences be pie filling Tl that is nearly WWIme WTflmg; the “1101331,: the ”Miler; lilolesaje pric. Change the m; 60min“, Pricing in ”(We $1.29 dc”land Schedule We \ 6- Hart 4.37%“) ECQnO 47 a range of price changes, up to nine cents per pound or per item. Because of this behavioral tendency on the part of consumers not to respond to price changes in this range, gocery retailers tend not to change retail prices on these individual gocery items even if the cost of food ingedients may have dropped by as much as nine cents. When this practice is applied to commodity-based processed food products, this hinders the flow of information on supply conditions from gower to consumer, since significant increases in supply may not be reflected at the retail level.” 3.2.1. Example 01' Vertical Coordination Problems: The Behavior of Food Retailers and Manufacturers This illustrative example relates to the above-mentioned gocery retailer SOP of pricing on the nines. Retailers observe that consumers respond very little to price differences between, for example, $1.30 and $1.39 for a consumer-sized can of tart cherry pie filling. Thus demand is highly inelastic and can be represented by a demand schedule that is nearly vertical in that range, as shown in Figure 20. Although the intersection of supply schedule S, with the demand schedule indicates that a price of $1.37 would be charged, this is not what is commonly practiced by retailers for many products. Instead, if the wholesale price per can plus a standard retail margin is anywhere in that ten-cent range, the retailer’s SOP is to round up the price charged consumers to $1.39. Only if the wholesale price plus the standard margin is above $1.39 or below $1.30 will the gocer change the retail price per can, and the price will be increased or decreased by 10 cents to continue pricing on the nines. Thus the demand schedule becomes more elastic at a point just above $1.29, $1.39, etc. Since demand is similarly inelastic for each segnent of the demand schedule, retailers will tend to price on the nines in a number of different price ranges. "Larry G. Hamm, ”Food Distribution Procurement Practices: Their Implications for ‘ Food System Structure and Coordination,” unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, East Lansing, 1981. Cir 1111 to: I‘m, 48 Figure 20. Demand Schedule with Pricing on the Nines by Grocery Retailer P=$1.49 4 D Demand schedule is more elastic at points such as these where retailers price on the nines. P=$1.39 —~ ‘ , =$1.37 Sa Consumers respond little to price P=$1 .29 — \ differences in this range. P=$1.19 A "l 00 Q The discussion above appears to imply that the segments in the demand schedule are vertical, representing infinitely inelastic demand. However, the segments are drawn to represent highly inelastic demand, but not infinite. What this means is that if pricing on the nines is commonly practiced for canned cherries, then quantity adjustments are taking place in other parts of the tart cherry market. Other tart cherry products are accumulating as inventories or having prices reduced. However, it is assumed for purposes of this analysis that this effect is not large, and that the impacts of retail price non-responsiveness to supply changes represent a significant problem in vertical coordination as described below. Assuming supply schedule S,| as the point of comparison from which to continue the analysis, the next step in the example is to examine what happens with a supply increase or decrease. A larger crop is represented by a supply shift to St, in Figure 21, where standard supply-demand analysis would indicate a price of $1.31 would prevail. However, since 8,, intersects the same segnent of the demand schedule as S,, retailers tend to charge the same 49 Figure 21. Retail Price and Product Movement for Supply Increase or Decrease P=$1.49 — '30 5b D\7 Sc P=$1.41 _ P=$1.39 — /‘ =$1.37 / P=$1.31 / . “'K 1:41.29 _ /// P=$1.19 - 00 3c Q retail price as before ($1.39) due to pricing on the nines. Due to the ability of the retailer to charge a price of $1.39 despite the higher level of supplies of that commodity, the quantity demanded at retail stays at the same level (0.), that would be expected if the supply schedule intersected the demand schedule at the point where price equals $1.39. If, however, an even larger crop causes a shift in supply to Sc, supply intersects demand in the next lower segnent, and the retailer will round the price charged per can to $1.29. A smaller crop is represented by a supply shift in the opposite direction, from S,| to 8,. In this case, supply intersects the next higher segnent of the demand schedule and a price of $1.49 is charged. Even though in this example the magnitude of the shift would suggest that a price of $1.41 be charged, the retailer charges $1.49 due to pricing on the nines. Although the supply shifts to SI, and S,' are of about the same magnitude, the supply increase to S. results in no change in price while the supply decrease to 8,, results in a price change of ten cents. This provides a partial explanation for the common experience of food 50 manufacturers that retailers will readily increase price in response to a shortage, but resist lowering price in response to increased supplies and lower gower and wholesale prices. This is a key aspect of the lack of effective vertical coordination that can occur in perennial crop subsectors due to retailer SOPs. It should be noted that farm level demand does not exhibit the stepped character of the retail demand function. This partly because only a portion of farm sales are destined for a single retail consumer product such as pie filling. The remainder of the crop is sold for industrial use in food service and as ingedients in the manufacture of other food products where the demand is somewhat more price elastic. Retailer behavior and consumer demand for retail processed products nevertheless exert a strong influence on farm level demand. In addition, SOPs relating to raw product pricing at the gower-first handler stage do not suggest a stepped demand function, so the gower level demand function is represented by a straight line. Because of inelastic demand at the farm level, large crops represented by 8,, and Sc in Figure 22 bring about steep price declines from P. to Pb and PC but only small increases in quantity demanded from Q. to Oh and Q. A short crop represented by a supply shift to Sd induces a substantial farm-level price increase from P. to Pd. Further insight is gained by examining pricing at several subsector stages as shown in the following gaphs (Figure 23, Figure 24, and Figure 25). Since the price impact at the initial processor stage is similar to that of the gower, the processor stage is not presented separately. The key here is the effect on pricing behavior resulting from the manufacturer’s awareness of the retailer tendency to price on the nines. The manufacturer in this example (Figure 24) has a stepped demand function similar to that of the retailer, and the manufacturer’s sales prices range from $1.15 to $0.91. These representative price levels were determined from a retailer price of $1.49 per can including a 30% goss margin. 51 Figure 22. Farm Level Demand P 5Q Sb Pd - D d 50 Pa Pb — Pc - 4.90 t i Qd Qb QC Q Representative manufacturer price levels were determined by declining from $1.49 in eight cent increments, representing approximately a 30% margin at each retail price level. If supply shifts from S,I to 3,, the manufacturer keeps the price at $1.07 based on the observation that retailers will generally not change the price per can for a supply shift of that magnitude. Thus, typical consumer behavior of being unresponsive to price changes of less than ten cents, if it is combined with the ability of retailers and manufacturers to hold prices at the upper end of a ten-cent range, results in no increase in sales of consumer-sized cans of pie filling despite a nine cent decrease in gower price due to the large crop (Figure 23). The quantity represented by Q. minus Oc is surplus and may become unsold carryover stocks at the processor level. Other possibilities are that the surplus will not move beyond the gower level and will either not be harvested or if the cherries are harvested they will not be sold. Thus price declines may occur in this situation at the processor and gower 52 Figure 23. Effect of Supply Increase on Tart Cherry Grower Price per Pound $0.27“4 $0.18 ‘ $0.361, 9-eent weer price dedte l 1 00 l’ ‘Oc 0b 0 Figure 24 Effect of Supply Increase on Manufacturer Price per Can, Tart Cherry Pie Filling P=$i .49 ‘4 P=$1.39 * P=$i.29 — =$1.19 A Sc “hwyhpaep. menu. SateSc. Wreflceeerteeper eat 10 Metefljt 03 02 on 0 Figure 25. Effect of Supply Increase on Retail Price Per Can of Tart Cherry Pie Filling P=$1.15 ‘4 P=$i.07 -‘ =$o.99 P=$O.91 — 03' 02 Ob Q 53 levels, but not at the manufacturer and retailer level, indicating ineffective coordination between subsector stages. In the event of a very large crop (a shift from S, to Sc), the retailer will price on the nines and drop the price per can ten cents from $1.39 to $1.29 (Figure 25). The manufacturer reduces price by the same amount to 99¢. However, the impact is larger at the gower level (Figure 23). Grower price drops by 18¢, but there is little additional increase in sales. When this occurs, the limited effectiveness of passing market signals relating to supply conditions downstream to consumers indicates that there are problems of coordinating supply and demand for commodity-based processed products. Large crops can thus bring about sharp price declines to gowers, yet even significant declines in gower prices frequently result in only small increases in quantity demanded at retail. Note that up to this point, the analysis assumes that there are no promotions, coupons, or ”two for $2.79" specials that alter these relationships. The effects of merchandising and promotion are introduced later. 3.2.1.1. Other Factors Affecting Price Transmission in the Subsector Other retailer SOPs such as product-line pricing can also hinder transmission of price sigials in a subsector. Cherry pies provide a useful example. Suppose that a large crop brings about a nine cent decline in the price of raw cherries and a ten cent decline in the price per pound of frozen cherries. The frozen cherry price change is lower since there are 1.11 pounds of raw cherries in a pound of frozen cherries.” If one pie uses one pound of cherries, ingedient cost declines by 10¢. In our example, a gocery store carries a line of frozen fruit pies (cherries, apples, and blueberries) all priced originally at $3.79. The 10¢ z"Substantial weight is lost through pitting and sorting cherries, and some of the juice is lost. After adding back sugar and freezing the cherries in the form known as "five plus one”, one pound of the frozen product contains the equivalent of 1.11 pounds of the original raw product. 54 decline in ingedient cost is not likely to induce substantially increased sales because the retailer prefers to maintain the same price for the entire line. One reason is that the retailer is aware that a price change of less than ten cents is not likely to induce many consumers to purchase additional cherry pies. Since the retailer does not change consumer prices in this example, the manufacturer tends to adopt a parallel pricing structure involving ranges within which changes in raw product price changes will not induce any price changes at the manufacturer level. An additional factor is that the raw product cost of processed food products is often a small part of total cost. Therefore in many instances changes in raw product cost due to shifts in production levels from year to year have little impact on the manufacturer’s pricing decisions for particular food products. Manufacturers also have long planning horizons for making pricing and promotion decisions. By the time supply changes become evident in a given year, a manufacturer may already have pricing and promotion decisions in place for the year, and if so, will see little advantage in changing those decisions because tart cherry supplies have increased in that particular year. In this example, lower gower and processor price by themselves are again unable to provide adequate subsector coordination to signal consumers of increased supplies. Supplemental mechanisms such as promotion and merchandising of commodity- based products can improve coordination in this situation. 3.2.2. The Impact of Annual Supply Variation Annual supply variation in perennial crops contributes to vertical coordination problems in part because of problems relating to transmission of price signals vertically through the subsector stages. In this section, vertical coordination problems are illustrated through a series of supply-demand diagams that represent vertically linked subsector stages. The diagams show the impact on prices of annual supply fluctuations at several subsector stages. The ”stepped" character of the demand curves in the previous set of diagams is also 55 applicable to the demand curves shown below. However, to make the diagams more readable, the demand curves below are not represented with separate segmented steps, but with a straight line. The first set of diagams appear in Figure 26 through Figure 29, illustrating the impact of a short tart cherry crop (a decrease in annual supply). Interpretation of the gaphs begins by looking first at Figure 26, the gower level (stage one of the subsector) and then moving sequentially through Figure 27 (processors), Figure 28 (manufacturers) and Figure 29 (retailers). The supply-demand gaphs represent exchange between subsector stages. The intersection of supply and demand at the gower level (stage one, Figure 26) indicates the gower price and a quantity of raw cherries which is exchanged between the gower stage and the initial processing stage. Figure 27 (stage two) represents exchange between the initial processor and the food manufacturer. Quantities in Figure 27 are processed cherries sold at f.o.b. processor prices. Figure 28 (stage three) represents exchange between the food manufacturer and the gocery retailer, with the quantity and price of canned tart cherries on the horizontal and vertical axes. Exchange between retailers and consumers is shown in Figure 29 (stage 4), with price representing the retail price charged in gocery stores, and quantity is the amount of canned tart cherries sold by gocery stores to consumers. Given that overview of what the gaphs represent, the next step is a more detailed analysis. Tart cherry industry observers indicate that supply decreases are reflected more effectively through the vertical system than are supply increases, and this is what is shown in the gaphical analysis. Returning to Figure 26 (stage one), an initial equilibrium is represented by the intersection of SI and D., with price P. and quantity 0.. With a short crop in a particular year, raw product supply shifts from S. to Sb. Linking this gaph by dotted lines with gaphs representing downstream stages is a means to illustrate a key aspect of vertical coordination -- the means by which the supply decrease is reflected vertically through the subsector stages. 56 ANNUAL SUPPLY DECREASE: FOUR SUBSECTOR STAGES Figure 26. Impact of Supply Decrease on Growers (Stage One) Sb 11/ Pb Pb' Pa Db \.. 0 Short crop: Raw product supply shifts from So to Sb. This is reflected vertically through the subsector stages. Pb Pb' Pa Ob 00 Figure 27. Impact of Supply Decrease on Processors (Stage Two) 75" a Processed supply shifts Db from So to Sb. \.. Ob Dc 57 Figure 28. Impact of Supply Decrease on Manufacturers (Stage Three) Pb ‘ “Sb 0 Responding to lower 'processed suppfies, (Pb)' manufacturers cut Pa l back on promotions, merchandising allowances, etc. Db\ Do Ob 00 Figure 29. Impact of Supply Decrease on Retailers (Stage Four) Pb l “Sb 0 Pb' With reduction in manufacturer— Pa sponsored promotion, retailer ” reduces merchandising and demand shifts from Do to Db. Db Do Ob Oa 58 In Figure 27 (stage two), the impact of the smaller crop is to shift processed cherry supply from S. to Sb. Responding to lower levels of processed supplies coming from processors, manufacturers in Figure 28 (stage three) cut back on merchandising allowances and other forms of promotion. With the reduction in manufacturer-sponsored promotion, the retailer (Figure 29, stage 4) responds by reducing merchandising activity, which has the effect of reducing demand, shifting D. to Db. Although the supply decrease by itself would have meant an increase in price from Pa to Pb, due to the dampened demand from reduced promotion, the price increase is smaller, rising from P. to Pb’. This price change is reflected upstream in the vertical system to manufacturers, processors and gowers with prices differing at successive stages by the amount of the retail, manufacturer and processor margins.21 Thus the vertical transmission of price changes due to moderate supply decreases in this example is accomplished reasonably effectively. The same is often not true, however, for supply increases. Beginning with Figure 30 (stage one), the intersection of S. and D represent an initial equilibrium. A large crop is represented by a shift in raw product supply from S. to 8c in Figure 30 and correspondingly processed supply in Figure 31 shifts from S, to 8,. However, the supply increase may not be effectively vertically coordinated beyond the manufacturer stage to the retailer stage (Figure 33). Returning to the gaphical analysis, Figure 30 shows that if supply changes originating at the farm level indicate a price change of up to 9¢ at retail, price may remain at P. and not decline to Pc, which would have been consistent with the shift in supply from S. to Sc. The lack of a price decline in this example is attributed to the above mentioned retailer standard operating procedure of ”pricing on the nines." Manufacturers (Figure 32) respond to this retailer practice by holding their price at P” despite the supply increase. 21These margins may vary from time to time depending on market conditions and the strategies of different firms. 59 ANNUAL SUPPLY INCREASE: FOUR SUBSECTOR STAGES Figure 30. Impact of Supply Increase on Growers (Stage One) ’50 D Sc Pa Large crop: Raw product supply shifts from So to (Sc and price declines, but P the supply increase is not C / effectively reflected to manufacturer and retailer stages. 00 00 Figure 31. Impact of Supply Increase on Processors (Stage Two) éa Sc Pa Processed supply shifts from So to Sc. Processed price declines. Pc / 00' 0c 60 Figure 32. Impact of Supply Increase on Manufacturers (Stage Three) Sc Pa Due to manufacturer and retailer SOPs, retail price remains at P0 despite Pc d supply increase to Sc. Without additional merchandising, quantity demanded remains at 00. 00 01: D Sc Pa Due to retailer SOPs, price remains at P0 despite supply shift to Sc. P Without merchandising, o" quantity demanded remains at 00 and (Qa-Qc) is unsold grower surplus. 00 0c 61 Without additional merchandising, quantity demanded remains at Q.. As discussed above, the quantity represented by 0. minus 0. is surplus and may become unsold carryover stocks at the processor level or unharvested cherries at the gower level. 3.2.2.1. Analysis of the Effects of Merchandising This outcome of unsold stocks or unharvested cherries can be altered somewhat with effective merchandising by manufacturers and retailers. Figure 34 through Figure 37 represent the same situation with a supply increase depicted in Figure 30 through Figure 33. The difference is that merchandising by manufacturers or retailers stimulates increased demand at the retail level as shown by the shift from D. to Dc in Figure 37. Price remains at P. due to pricing on the nines by the retailer, but quantity demanded at P. increases from Q. to O... This has the effect of improving coordination, since the quantity sold (0..) more nearly matches the quantity produced by gowers (0.). There is improved vertical coordination through the subsector stages since the increase in demand due to increased retailer merchandising increases the quantity of raw product demanded at the gower level (stage one). The purpose of this gaphical analysis has been to show that pricing SOPs can hinder the flow of supply and demand information through the vertical marketing system, and that effective merchandising can improve the situation. The next section deals with some of the specific means by which merchandising accomplishes this. 3.2.2.2. The Impact of Merchandising Because of these problems in coordinating demand with short-run shifts in supply, manufacturers and generic promotion organizations rely partly on various non-price methods such as couponing to reflect supply changes to consumers and to increase sales. Table 8 and Figure 38 show the effects of various alternative merchandising techniques on product movement. 62 ANNUAL SUPPLY INCREASE WITH MERCHANDISING: 4 SUBSECTOR STAGES Figure 34. Impact of Supply Increase on Growers (Stage One) /sa Pa Increase in demand from retailer and manufacturer increases quantity of raw product demanded from 00 to Om. PC“ /QDC Oa Qm AVOC Figure 35. Impact of Supply Increase on Processors (Stage Two) ea 0 Pa Pc “ / a DC 00 Om lOC 63 Figure 36. Impact of Supply Increase on Manufacturers (Stage Three) éd C Pa Pc _ / DC] DC 00 Om iQC Figure 37. Impact of Supply Increase on Retailers (Stage Four) Dc DO 0 P0 With merchandising, Da shifts to Dc. Price remains at P0, but quantity demanded increases Pc - from 00 to Om. Oa Om iQC: 64 Table 8 shows a number of merchandising actions that can be taken in retail stores to increase sales temporarily. The techniques in the first and second categories in Table 8 are all non-price methods to communicate with consumers about specific products. The third category indicates that combinations of several techniques plus price changes have the strongest impact. Merchandising with methods such as these can contribute to improved vertical coordination when they are implemented to increase sales in response to increased supplies due, for example, to a large crop. Since normal pricing SOPs are often not adequate in adjusting retail sales to changing supply conditions in the subsector, the merchandising can provide very important supplemental coordination roles. However, retailers rarely undertake merchandising efforts on behalf of specific products on their own. They must be induced to undertake specific promotions by manufacturers, other suppliers, or generic commodity promotion organizations. For example, a manufacturer may offer a promotional allowance of five cents per can, provide in-store display materials, and induce an ageement from the retailer to run a newspaper advertisement. In some cases the manufacturers will pay an advertising allowance for a local advertisement and possibly offer coupons. Figure 38 shows that one effect of the merchandising is to temporarily shift the demand schedule to the right so that the supply schedule representing the large crap (8.) intersects the DD"... demand schedule (which reflects the impact of merchandising) at a point that will bring forth increased sales. The sales increase is the difference between O. and Qm- Price is not changed, so this represents the application of non-price coordination methods. Within a week to possibly a few weeks after the end of a promotion, the merchandising effect wears off, demand shifts back to the left, and sales return to their pre- PrOmotion level. If only a single promotion is undertaken, this promotional impact is particularly likely to be short-lived for commodity-based products considered to be of minor impox-tance from the retailer’s point of view, including tart cherry products. For this reason, 65 Table 8. Effects of Temporary Merchandising Techniques on Product Movement . Technique Description impact on Sales' 1. Use of off- a. End-aisle display with special price compared to shelf shelf (special) location with same special price. No advertising. +420% displays b. Same as 1a. but with the addition of more colorful, elaborate signs +542% 2. Use of shelf a. Use of simple sign with no advertising and no product signs with name identification + 5% no price b. Use ‘of sign with product name identification and price reduction specified but no advertising +39% c. Use of simple ”as advertised“ sign to point out advertised product on shelf compared to same product without a sign. + 124% 3. Combinations a. Product advertised in newspaper with special price of various combined with a simple shelf sign ”as advertised at iota” + 194% techniques b. Same as 1a. above with the addition of end-aisle display +629% c. Same as lb. but with manufacturer ”theme sale" making use of store-wide banners, point-of-purchase materials, etc. +782% :- 1Impact of a specific promotion may last for up to several weeks after the promotion takes place, after which product sales will generally return to the pro-promotion level. The results reported above are from a special study conducted by Progessive Grocer in 1970. The numbers are intended only to provide a general picture of the impact of alternative merchandising techniques, and reliance should not be placed on specific percentages. Percentage changes in sales in response to promotions vary geatly by commodity, market and time period. These figures represent averages of several products over several time periods. The study consisted of testing various merchandising techniques in sets of one company‘s stores matched for volume, design, size, and demogaphies. Reported in: Larry G. Hamm, ”Food Distributor Procurement Practices: Their Implications for Food System Structure and Coordination.” Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Dept. of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, East Lansing, 1981, 416-17. _ Figure 38. Effect of Temporary Merchandising on Retail Demand With Supply Increase P=$i.49 4 P=$i.39 -* P=$i.29 — Dmerch JJ+Omch Q 66 to have a significant impact on increasing sales as a means to respond to increases in supply at the farm and processor level, there needs to be several related promotions timed sequentially throughout the year. It should be acknowledged that promotions including coupon offerings generally reduce the price of a food product, e.g. a price of 59¢ is reduced to two for 99¢. Coupon promotions are frequently targeted to the more price responsive buyers. Increases in sales that result from the coupon promotion are therefore represented in economic analysis both in terms of moving along the demand curve as well as shifting the curve. Nevertheless, the analysis about the role of merchandising and promotion in coordinating demand with variable supply still holds. Hamm offers useful observations that help to put the foregoing analysis into perspective. Writing in 1981, he pointed out that brand manufacturers were getting out of the commodity business, largely because returns were higher with more highly processed foods and because of the additional cost incurred by marketing commodity-based products with variable supplies. Some 10F branded food product manufacturers that continued to market commodity products have tended to rely on processors to supply product for the manufacturer label. The processor then bore the risk and cost of supply variability. Hamm pointed out that manufacturers thus avoided the need to bear coordination costs by shifting the coordination role to upstream stages in the subsector (processors and growers). As the brand manufacturers have reduced some aspects of their vertical coordination role, private label processors have had to increasingly bid against each other for retail buyer attention. A frequent result is that is insufficient merchandising and increased reliance on price as the main coordination mechanism. In large crop years inventory backs up and the private label 67 suppliers bear the cost. In short crop years, supplies are depleted quickly and retail prices may be higher than economically necessary.22 Thus many manufacturers no longer perform the role of inducing retailers to undertake merchandising to increase sales of commodity-based food products. Alternative coordination mechanisms that fill the supply-demand balancing roles as IOF food manufacturers have shifted away from those roles are introduced in Section 3.3 below. 3.2.3. Consumer Demand: Matching Product Attributes to Consumer Preferences Another dimension of coordination addressed in this research is that of matching product attributes, grades, qualities, and varieties with consumer preferences. Table 9 provides an illustrative list of key product attributes. The linkage between food product attributes and the vertical production-distribution system is illustrated below in Figure 39 using a concept map which combines Table 9 and the subsector stages in Table 7.23 As shown in the diagram, consumers have buying strategies which are based on tastes and preferences for perceived specific attributes of food products. Firms at various stages of a particular subsector attempt to use various coordination mechanisms to determine the product attributes and appropriate quantities desired by participants in downstream stages. Price is a primary coordination mechanism, and other ones include contractual arrangements, grades and quality specifications and other forms of market information. Firms adapt production, handling, processing, and distribution methods to produce food with the attributes that they perceive are preferred by consumers and to provide the necessary services to intermediate customers who are in downstream stages in 22Hamm, "Food Distributor Procurement Practices.” 23Adaptation of diagram from Deborah H. Streeter and others, "Information Technology, Coordination, and Competitiveness 1n the Food and Agribusiness Sector, mm W December 1991, 1467. 68 Table 9. Food Product Attributes Variety Availability (e.g., seasonal versus year-round) Convenience Price Stability Taste Color Quality Nutrition Food Safety Environmental Impacts the subsector. Firms also develop marketing strategies which are based on attempts to discover consumer tastes and preferences and/or to influence them. For branded food product manufacturers (cooperatives or IOFs) as well as commodity-oriented firms and organizations, marketing strategies are directed at discovering and influencing the merchandising SOPs of retail food distributors. This elicitation of preferences and development of strategies to provide products and services to match those preferences is part of the process of coordination. Large food retail firms are in some respects more able to identify key characteristics and potential demand for food products than are commodity processors or growers. However, Hamm points out that retail food distributors have little incentive to transmit that demand information to firms upstream in the vertical system. Instead, the characteristics and variety of food products offered to consumers are largely determined by the standard Operating procedures of, and interactions between, purchasing agents and merchandisers of large retail chains on the one hand, and marketing agents of food manufacturers on the 69 Figure 39. Coordination Linkages of Subsector Stages with Consumer Demand Stages in Agricultural Subsectors / Consumers M ed by Banting Strategies Buying Strategies _——M on $332.32; \ \ / et rout iscovery . SOP t Do - mar Prices MW suit; 5.33.. w alers Product attributes r Coordination \acltates / -~ Food ' ' eds Mautachrers ] Mecmn sms use m -_. k hformation I...“ _ hmd ' d through Availability Processor/ 7 Convenience Hmders Coordination [ )— ttroudi regains \ [Price Stcbility ]—- W... M. “V009“ Timing/Schedding Nutrition Consistency/ ‘ "9*” Em 50f“), }_ Assurmce Environmental Concerns ' other. The outcomes of these interactions severely limit the effective access of new products and products from new and small firms.” A key part of the interaction between retailer and manufacturer is that retailers need to be convinced by manufacturers that a particular new food product will be accepted by consumers. Retailers generally expect manufacturers to carry out market research to determine consumer preferences and the means by which product characteristics can be designed and promoted to appeal to those preferences. The market research, test marketing and promotion are costly undertakings often beyond the reach of small firms. Growers, processors, manufacturers and others in the production-distribution system need detailed information about product demand, including preferences for specific product 2“Hamm, "Food Distributor Procurement Practices." 70 attributes, in successive steps of the vertical chain. Food manufacturers generally invest significant resources in market research on consumer preferences. Large brand manufacturers generally have quite effective market research and new product development. However, such research is generally not oriented toward increasing sales for food products from a particular commodity. For this reason growers of a specific commodity whose production is increasing, or is highly variable, have incentives to take collective action in the form of supporting commodity-oriented organizations that carry out market research and generic commodity promotion that can contribute to subsector coordination. How that is carried out is examined in Chapter 4. In markets coordinated primarily by prices, demand is articulated primarily through decisions to buy or to refrain from such actions. However, food products have a number of actual and potential attributes, and sales data in such markets provide very limited information about consumer preferences. Since it is costly for consumers to express their preferences directly to commodity processors, manufacturers, other suppliers, and growers, the most likely consumer reaction to dissatisfaction with any particular attribute is not to buy the product.25 Thus there are difficulties in transmitting information on consumer preferences for product attributes to firms in successive stages of a commodity subsector. This contributes to problems of balancing supply and demand. Thus there is a role for supplemental coordinating mechanisms which address the problems and shortcomings of relying primarily on market prices to balance supply and demand for perennial crop commodities. The graphical examples above illustrated the problems of vertical transmission of pricing signals through states of a perennial crop subsectors. Part of the function of cooperatives, marketing orders, commodity promotion EA. 0. Hirschman, Mm Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970. 71 commissions and other marketing institutions is to facilitate the price system in the task of vertical coordination. The nature of those coordination mechanisms is examined next. 3.3. Market Coordination Mechanisms and Balancing Subsector Supply and Demand Coordination mechanisms for market exchange between growers and IOF handlers/ processors take a variety of forms, a few examples of which include open price contracts, contracts in which prices or price formulas are specified, non-contractual and verbal agreements and so on. Another alternative that may facilitate subsector coordination is vertical integration through combined ownership of farms, initial processing and food manufacturing (combining subsector stages one, two and three from Figure 19 in section 3.1). Vertical integration could help gain market access for growers, and problems of short- run supply variability could be addressed through large scale storage. However, vertical integration through combined ownership of farms and processing facilities adjacent vertical stages such as processing and is not the dominant pattern observed in perennial crop subsectors. Although grower-processors operate in both the tart cherry and almond subsectors, they do not play a significant market coordination role. Given the conditions described in Chapter 2 and the coordination problems introduced in this chapter, a key question is what market coordination mechanisms are best suited to helping to improve the balance of supply and demand in a subsector? The prevalence of cooperatives and the existence of certain types of government-facilitated coordination in the raisin, almond, and tart cherry subsectors suggests that other types of grower-IOF coordination mechanisms are often inadequate for addressing supply-demand balancing problems in certain subsectors. The foregoing graphical and discussion of the consequences of supply variability show that grower-IOF coordination mechanisms can and do fail to address supply-demand balancing problems in certain subsectors. Chapter 4 and Chapter 5 explore in detail the 72 ways in which cooperative coordination and government-facilitated coordination offer alternatives. This last term requires some clarification. In a broad sense, numerous aspects of coordination across markets are facilitated by government. Market exchange is facilitated by performance of such functions as contract enforcement, establishing standards, and determining which individuals have which specific rights when interests conflict. There also appears to be some overlap between cooperative coordination and government-facilitated coordination in that the very existence of cooperatives depends on enabling legislation such as the Capper-Volstead Act. However, in this research the term government-facilitated coordination is used more narrowly to apply to some specific instances where government action is initiated to address a specific set of market coordination problems. These government actions include the creation of federal marketing orders and financing of generic commodity demand expansion organizations if these are supported by a state or federal marketing order. In the second category in Table 1 (government-facilitated coordination mechanisms) are two supply-demand balancing mechanisms: federal marketing order supply management and generic commodity demand expansion. Federal and state marketing orders are a form of collective action by growers (and in some cases processors) that can facilitate some forms of industry-wide cooperation in managing subsector supply or demand-related problems. Growers can vote to establish a marketing order for improved industry marketing performance based on legal guidelines established by the federal government or by some indiVidual state governments, with mandatory provisions that generally apply to all growers and handlers in a market. The almond and raisin federal marketing orders have both been in effect for over 40 years. The tart cherry federal marketing order was in effect from 1972 ‘0 1 986. Marketing order supply management issues are examined in Chapter 5. 73 Table 10. Examples of Coordinating Mechanisms in Three Perennial Crop Subsectors Coordinating Mechanism Almonds Raisins Cherries COOPERATIVE COORDINATION #1 Committed Commodity Marketing Cooperative X #2 Committed Integrated Marketing Cooperative X X #3 Cooperative/Corporation Joint Venture X #4 Bargaining Cooperative X X GOVERNMENT-FACILITATED COORDINATION Federal Marketing Order Supply Management A. Reserve Pool Storage X X X B. Market Allocation X X X C. Nonharvest or Non-production Diversion X” X D. Acreage Removal X” Generic Conunodity Demand Expansionc A. Research and Development F S F,S B. Advertising and Promotion F S S,N C. Export Promotion F ,OF F,OF,S F,OF,S,N D. Allocation to New Product Development F F F Through Federal Marketing Order 'IOF - Investor-owned firm, as distinguished from a cooperative, which is patron—owned firm I'I'he Raisin Diversion Program reduces raisin grape acreage temporarily (through spur pruning) or permanently (through vine removal). cFrafederal marketing order; OF=other federal government programs; S=state marketing order, An important issue related to generic commodity demand expansion is how the programs are funded. Raisin and tart cherry promotion programs are funded by mandatory grower assessments arranged through state marketing orders in some states. Major organizations for carrying out these programs are the California Raisin Advisory Board (CALRAB) and the Cherry Marketing Institute (CMI). Almond generic promotion is funded and carried out through the federal marketing order administrative board, the Almond Board of California (ABC). The role of government-facilitated coordination is examined in more detail in Chapter 5. The discussion above suggested that since retailers and non-grower-owned food manufacturers are not commodity-oriented, coordinating supplies from agricultural production with consumer demand is generally left to firms that m commodity-oriented, 74 including agricultural marketing cooperatives. But what specific advantages do cooperatives have in addressing commodity supply-demand balancing problems? 3.4. Advantages of Cooperatives Cooperatives do not play these coordination roles in certain commodity subsectors by accident, but rather because they have some advantages in organizing certain marketing functions for their members that are growers of the commodity in question. This section presents briefly a few of the key arguments in the agricultural economics literature regarding these advantages. The arguments do not pertain to marketing of any specific crop. Staatz points out some of the reasons why cooperatives in some cases are the preferable means to organize transactions between growers and downstream stages in a subsector". “A farmer cooperative firm...represents a looser form of vertical integration than a vertically integrated IOF...Stockholders in the cooperative firm agree to eschew competition among themselves in their marketing and input supply activities but continue to make the rest of their decisions independently. Cooperative firms therefore allow their members to capture many of the advantages of large-scale marketing, input production, and strategic planning while still permitting farmers to make most of their farm-level decisions themselves. Thus while there are often strong reasons for vertically integrating between farming and certain marketing and input supply activities, the decentralized nature of cooperatives make them a more efficient way of carrying out that integration than an IOF.” Another reason for the existence of agricultural cooperative firms is the preservation of grower market options. Growers facing the prospect of large capital losses on farm assets if they have no market because of the closing of an investor-owned processing plant are often motivated to purchase the processing facilities to convert them into processing- marketing cooperatives. Growers organized into cooperatives are likely to be willing in many cases to operate market facilities that IOFs have abandoned because cooperatives take into account the joint profitability of farming and marketing, not simply the profitability of 2‘John Staatz, "Farmers’ Incentives to Take Collective Action Via Cooperatives: A Transactions Cost Approach," in 00 e ative eo : New roaches Jeffrey S. Royer, ed., Service Report 18, Agricultural Cooperative Service, USDA, July 1987, 98. 75 marketing functions alone. Peterson addresses this issue in his classification of cooperative strategies. He developed a taxonomy of six returns strategies and six risk management strategies followed by cooperatives. Peterson refers to the strategy of producing returns for growers in times when non-cooperative firms would abandon a market as a ”maintain the market" strategy.” However, the joint profitability argument alone is not sufficient to explain why cooperatives exist, since growers could renegotiate contracts with IOF marketing firms to make the latter more profitable and thus preserve their market options. There must be reasons why this renegotiation of contracts sometimes does not take place. One reason is that if growers bargain collectively, they may choose not to make price concessions due to grower uncertainty as to the IOF processor’s true financial situation. If supplies and prices are volatile, IOFs can incur heavy losses if they have to commit to a raw product price before they know what prices they will receive for their processed products. In a cooperative, there can be a somewhat more open flow of financial information among system participants, and farmers can have more confidence that a reduction in prices is not due to opportunistic behavior.28 This brief discussion of coordination roles leads us to a related question: Since there are many types of cooperatives, which ones are most suited to deal with the above- mentioned supply-demand balancing problems? The following section presents four types of cooperatives. ”Christopher J. Peterson, e o 'c ole of icultural Coo erat'v : etu sa W Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Cornell University, 1992. ”Staatz, 'Farmers’ Incentives to Take Collections Via Cooperatives," 92-93. 76 3.5. Types of Cooperatives and Balancing Supply and Demand Two particular types of cooperatives have the greatest potential to contribute to an improved balance of supply and demand in a subsector: (1) committed integrated marketing cooperatives and (2) committed commodity marketing cooperatives.” A key aspect of both types of committed marketing cooperatives is that although their priority commitment is to their members, they are large enough to be committed to influencing markets and marketing of the commodity as a whole through various means. New product development and market development achieved by these types of cooperatives results in greater overall sales of the commodity. The cooperatives also engage in other activities beneficial to other marketing firms such as dealing with legislative and regulatory matters and seeking to reduce foreign trade barriers. Examples of the cooperatives appear in Table 11. As shown in Table 11, additional types of cooperatives that have important roles in the three subsectors include bargaining cooperatives and cooperative-corporation joint ventures. This section briefly presents and defines several types of cooperatives and is intended only to set the context. Analysis on the role of cooperatives in coordinating supply and demand appear in Chapters 4 and 5. A key question is how one distinguishes CIMCs, CCMCs, and other types of cooperatives. 1. Committed Commodity Marketing goperative (CCMC). CCMCs have a goal of influencing demand and prices as well as maintaining strong marketing programs for a particular commodity. The CCMC may also at times attempt to influence market supplies through storage or other means. These cooperatives do not have a strong brand position, in contrast to committed integrated marketing cooperatives (#2 below). CCMC members typically make up a large proportion of the total number of producers of the commodity, and the cooperative is usually the largest marketing firm in a commodity subsector, or is 2"The terms committed commodity marketing cooperative and committed integrated marketing cooperative are adapted from work by Ronald A. Knutson. 77 Table 11. Types of' Cooperatives in Fruit, Nut, and Vegetable Industries t Type of Cooperative Examples from California Examples from Michigan i and Florida and other states ' l. Committed Commodity Citrus Central' 1. Cherry Central Marketing Cooperative (Florida) C00perative (CCMC) 2. MBG Marketing 2. Committed Integrated 1. Blue Diamond 1. National Grape Marketing Cooperative 2. Sun Maid C00perative (Welch) (CIMC) 3. Sunkist 2. Ocean Spray (MA) i 3. Cooperative/Corporation Curtice-Burns Profac Joint Venture (NY, MI) ‘ . 1 4. Bargaining Cooperative 1. Raisin Bargaining Assn. 1. MACMA-AAMA(MI) t 2. Calif. Canning Peach Assn. 2. Hazelnut Growers ! 3. Calif. Canning Pear Assn. Barg. Assn. (OR) 'No longer in business among the largest. An example of a CCMC in Florida was Citrus Central, which has now gone out of business. Although no longer in business, the quantity of citrus fruit marketed through the cooperatives represented a significant proportion of total Florida citrus production. Unlike Sunkist, Citrus Central did not market member production under a brand name. Michigan-based examples of CCMCs include Cherry Central Cooperative (CCC), a federated c00perative in the tart cherry industry, and MBG Marketing, a centralized COOperative in the blueberry industry. Cherry Central was formed to strengthen marketing, and to a lesser extent pricing, in cherry commodity markets. Influencing cherry prices has not been a major goal in recent years. Today CCC markets a variety of processed and fresh fruits and vegetables. It is one of the largest marketers in the U.S. of processed cherries, blueberries, and apples. Cherry Central currently has 17 processor members in Michigan, Utah, and Wisconsin. Most of the members are cherry processing cooperatives, although several are grower-processors. MBG Marketing is a member of CCC and is the sole supplier of blueberries to Cherry Central. 78 The goals and achievements of Cherry Central include influencing demand, maintaining strong marketing, and advancing grower and industry interests. However, because it is mainly involved in commodity marketing and does not directly market consumer branded products, it can be categorized as a committed commodity marketing cooperative rather than as a committed integrated marketing cooperative. Sales of consumer retail products, which provides the means for vertical coordination with downstream market levels, are achieved in part through membership in Profac cooperative, which has a joint venture arrangement with Curtice-Burns, an IOF food manufacturer. Cherry Central also markets some products under consumer brands, (through Curtice- Burns/Profac), but these are not strong national brands such as Sun-Maid or Blue Diamond. 2. Committed Integgated Marketing Cooperative (CIMC). CIMCs are more completely integrated than CCMCs in that they market a significant portion of their commodity as strongly branded consumer products. CIMCs thus provide an additional dimension beyond the CCMC by providing more direct access to retail consumer markets. An advantage that CIMCs have over CCMCs and other types of cooperatives is that prices are generally more stable at retail market levels and the benefits of this increased stability can be passed upstream to the growers.30 In Peterson’s taxonomy, pursuit of this risk management strategy of integrating into a more stable final market, is referred to as ”selective vertical integration." Examples of such cooperatives based in California with strong national brands are Sun Maid (raisins), Blue Diamond (almonds) and Sunkist (fresh citrus). Additional examples from other states include National Grape Cooperative (which markets processed 3"Ronald A. Knutson, "The Impact of Cooperatives on Market Performance, Subsector Coordination, and the Organization of Agriculture," in Agricultural Cooperatives and 1h; priic Interest: Egoceedings of a Noah Centrai Regional Research Committee Sponsoged Wozkshop, St. Lpuis, MQ, lime £8, 1972, NC. Project 117 Monograph 4, Research Division, College of Agricultural and Life Sciences, University of Wisconsin, Madison, September 1978, 306. 79 grape products under the Welch’s brand) and Ocean Spray (cranberries). This research for focused on Sun-Maid and Blue Diamond because it emphasized the almond and raisin subsectors. Peterson’s classification of cooperative strategies provides insights on how to distinguish types of cooperatives. Peterson classified twelve cooperative strategies: six strategies that are designed to improve member returns and six strategies that intended to reduce grower risk.31 Two of Peterson’s twelve strategies help define a CIMC: 1) the risk strategy of integrating into a stable final market and 2) the return strategy of serving a ”missing" final consumer market. A missing consumer market in the context of this research means the potential additional sales of commodity-based retail food products that could occur if new food products were developed or if sales were expanded into new geographic locations. Both Sun-Maid and Blue Diamond are able to reduce risk to their members through returns that are steadier due to more stable prices on their sales of branded retail products than are obtainable from bulk commodity sales of raisins or almonds. In addition, by development and promotion of new products and seeking additional market niches, both cooperatives are expanding sales for their members by serving "missing” final consumer markets. In so doing, they also serve a key supply-demand balancing role by increasing demand for products for which supply has been increasing. The means by which the cooperatives accomplished this task are the subject of Chapter 4. Sun-Maid Growers of California was created during the 19308 to provide additional market outlets for growers of raisin-type grapes. The cooperative markets a variety of retail package sizes and types under its brand name and it currently holds about a 50% share of the U.S. retail market for packaged raisins. The cooperative also markets significant quantities as industrial ingredients to food manufacturers. Sun Maid membership 31Peterson, :1th mnpmig Bole pi Agziculturai Cooperatives. 80 represented between 25-30% of total raisin production during the second half of the 19808. Sun Maid currently has approximately 1300 members. The California Almond Growers Exchange was formed in 1910, but was renamed Blue Diamond Growers of California in 1987. Rapid grth of California almonds since the late 19608 propelled Blue Diamond into becoming the world’s largest almond marketing firm. The cooperative’s share of total California almond production has fluctuated around 50% in recent years. Historically its share has been as high as 60%. Blue Diamond membership was approximately 4500 members in 1992. Although branded retail sales are important, a large proportion of the cooperative’s tonnage is sold in raw bulk form or as value-added ingredients for food manufacturers and food service customers. During the late 19808 and early 1990s, Blue Diamond was also selling 60-70% of its member’s production into the export market. 3. @pgrativelCogporagion Joint Venture. This arrangement combines a food manufacturing firm with a more commodity-oriented cooperative. An example is the long- term joint venture agreement between Profac Cooperative, the members of which supply a number of fruits and vegetables, and Curtice-Burns, Inc., which markets a number of branded food products. In the past, several joint ventures in the Florida citrus industry have also operated under somewhat similar joint venture arrangements. The joint venture approach represents another example of a more flexible approach to vertical coordination than is likely with ownership integration of vertical stages in a subsector. One major contribution of such an arrangement is to balance supply and demand for cherries, which may involve the cooperative’s use of stock tonnage as a means to limit the quantities that the cooperative will accept in surplus periods. However, stock tonnage is not used by some joint ventures. This approach is discussed in more detail in Chapter 5. 4. W. Bargaining cooperatives typically negotiate prices and sometimes other terms of trade with processors. A major contribution to vertical 81 coordination and balancing supply and demand is that the bargaining process provides a means to bring a great deal of supply and demand information to bear on the raw product pricing process. Bargaining cooperatives are also frequently influential in the support and maintenance of supply management programs through federal marketing orders and are generally supportive of demand expansion programs through generic commodity demand expansion organizations. California examples include the Raisin Bargaining Association, California Canning Peach Association and California Canning Pear Association. In Michigan, MACMA-AAMA bargains on behalf of producers in various Michigan commodity industries, including apples, asparagus, and tart cherries. MACMA-AAMA is the Michigan Agricultural Cooperative Marketing Association, which has historically been affiliated with American Agricultural Marketing Association (AAMA). 3.6. Summary A goal of this chapter was to make the case that a perennial crop subsector that relies primarily on market prices and exchange arrangements between growers and IOF handlers can experience significant coordination problems. The analysis of supply variability leads to several observations about perennial crop subsector impacts and actions to improve coordination. The foregoing pages described several factors that make sales of commodity- based food products relatively unresponsive to price declines that are unpublicized or otherwise unaccompanied by additional promotion. Food manufacturers and retailers recognize that the purchasing behavior of many consumers regarding certain processed food products is not very price responsive. As a result, SOPs of manufacturers and retailers include not changing certain retail food product prices despite changes that may have occurred in the cost of raw product due to volatility in agricultural production. Specific SOPs that were examined were pricing on the nines and product line pricing. In both eases, 82 raw product costs can vary over a substantial range before any retail price changes are made. When price changes are made, they tend to move in substantial increments such as ten cents per unit. An additional reason for the lack of price responsiveness is that the raw product cost of processed food products is often a small part of total cost. This reduces the pressure to adjust the selling price of the product in response to changes in the raw product cost. Also important is the competitive environment facing manufacturers and retailers. Retail stores carry thousands of products and decisions relating to pricing and price changes of individual food products depend on strategies developed to draw customers into retail grocery stores. These retailer strategies are in turn affected by the competitive actions of other retailers in the market area. Changes in raw product cost of food products from a particular commodity generally have very little impact on these decisions. Food manufacturers also have long planning horizons, and this is an additional reason that and their promotional and pricing decisions are not likely to be significantly altered in response to raw product supply fluctuations and changes in raw product cost. However, even if sales of certain processed food products are not generally 1' espOnsive to price changes alone, food product sales often mm responsive to a large number or Promotion and merchandising efforts. Retailers can be influenced to undertake merchandising actions to increase sales of particular food products. Such efforts to influence retailer merchandising generally come from food manufacturers. However, large bratitled food product manufacturers promote their own products and have no incentive to undertake such efforts for food products from a particular commodity in response to problems of supply variability. The graphical analysis showed that this lack of price responsiveness can result in big Price . . and revenue dechnes at the grower level in large crop years. These problems of sfiqm coordination can be addressed by collective action by growers. Although firms at 83 various subsector stages feel the consequences of the coordination problems, growers have the greatest incentive to undertake such action due to the severity of the negative impacts of supply volatility. At the grower level is the issue of individual versus collective benefit of taking action in response to supply variability. There are benefits to all growers if total demand for a commodity expands. However, for individual growers and individual IOF processors and manufacturers, the benefits of promoting food products as a "commodity" are not likely to exceed the costs. However, if funds can be collected to undertake promotional campaigns of sufficient size, there is often a benefit from generic commodity promotion. A greater payoff to promotion comes from successful differentiation of commodity-based food products through developing a brand franchise. Growers can express their collective interest in market expansion for commodity- based food products through the coordination mechanisms introduced in the previous section. C00perative coordination mechanisms included CIMCs and CCMCs. Committed integrated marketing cooperatives can expand demand by developing and promoting food prod nets with a cooperative brand franchise. Committed commodity marketing cooperatives gen erally command a sufficiently large proportion of total supply to enable them to influence man ufacturers to undertake new product development and promotion. Govemment- facilitated coordination mechanisms make up another major category. Growers can support generic commodity demand expansion programs by assessing money from growers (and sorne‘iixnes handlers) and allocating that money to promotional programs. Reliable supplies of raw product and predictable prices are key factors in getting an adecl‘lélte payoff from investment in promotion and in achieving effective product dlff‘e l"fitntiation and new product development. The reliability factor is a key aspect of Pet‘s “admg IOF food manufacturers to undertake food product promotion involving a 84 perennial crop commodity. The coordination mechanisms developed to address this issue, particularly federal marketing orders, are the subject of Chapter Five. Another goal of this chapter was to develop the framework to gain a general understanding of how cooperatives, and in particular committed marketing cooperatives, can address the coordination problems posed by the supply volatility described in Chapter Two. This framework is used in the next chapter to examine specific demand expansion efforts of CIMCs and CCMCs in the tart cherry, almond and raisin subsectors. CHAPTER 4: DEMAND ISSUES AND COORDINATION The previous chapters presented some of the problems associated with balancing supply and demand in perennial crop subsectors. The next step is to look at how certain roles played by committed marketing cooperatives and generic commodity promotion organizations address the problems of balancing supply and demand for perennial crops. This chapter examines both short-run demand issues relating to annual supply fluctuations and also long-run demand issues relating to the need to expand demand to balance supplies during periods of overproduction. 4.1. Demand Expansion and Cooperatives Contributing to the ability of CIMCs and CCMCs to perform vertical market coordinating roles such as demand expansion are: (1) cooperative membership that includes a large proportion of producers of a commodity and (2) a brand position through successful product differentiation of commodity-based retail products, and in some cases substantial financial resources that the cooperative can apply to developing and marketing new products. The strong brand position and new product development abilities of large coo[Jeratives in both the almond and raisin subsectors have enabled them to expand demand for member tonnage and indirectly influence overall demand for those commodities. Depending on cooperative market position and resources, cooperative demand expansion efforts tend to involve one or both of two main strategies: a commodity marketing Strateg' or a brand/value-added marketing strategy. Table 12 presents some of the key (inferences between the strategies. A commodity marketing strategy for a cooperative involves selling member production as a relatively undifferentiated commodity. Coo . . . peratrves that emphasrze a commodity strategy over a brand/value-added strategy Us“ a‘11), have little capacity to develop new retail products for consumers. 85 86 Table 12. Alternative Marketing Strategies in Perennial Crop Subsectors Commodity Marketing Strateg Brand/Value-added Marketing Strategy -Sell undifferentiated commodity -Have strong retail brands and market a variety of value-added food products designed to meet consumer preferences -Emphasize sales of members production -Focus on meeting consumer desires with a primarily with existing products to benefit wide variety of products & services based producers on consumer wants & preferences -Usually have little capacity to develop new -Have ability to develop a series of new products for different types of consumers products for different types of consumers preferences 4.2. Commodity Marketing A large proportion of almonds, raisins, and tart cherries are sold as relatively undifferentiated commodities by both investor-owned processors / handlers and cooperatives, including those cooperatives that have strong consumer brands. Because of the strong price competition and little product differentiation in commodity marketing, there are usually lower margins for the firm with this strategy than in the branded and value-added categories. However, the almond cooperative and some competing commodity marketing firms have some impact on their sales volumes in the commodity portion of the market by emphasizing high quality and guarantees of more reliable supply to attract the "quality buyers” while leaving "price buyers" to be supplied by other handlers.32 Thus even within the relatively undifferentiated commodity market, there are degrees of product dift‘fi‘vl‘entiation. The same is true to varying degrees in the other two subsectors. For example, in the commodity-oriented "brown almond" market, the almond perative will emphasize quality factors such an unusually low incidence of ”foreign \ h M Blue Diamond Growers, 1nc., July 1986, 39. 87 material." The cooperative also has "self-certification" arrangements, in which buyers will accept deliveries without inspection because of the buyer’s confidence in the cooperative’s quality.33 These cooperative approaches reduce transactions costs and facilitate coordination in regard to quality characteristics. 4.2.1. Undifferentiated Commodity Markets and Annual Supply Fluctuations Expanding or contracting demand as annual supplies fluctuate has been attempted to the extent possible in undifferentiated commodity markets. In a large-crop year, major attempts are usually made to sell larger quantities into the commodity markets, primarily through lower commodity prices, and prices to processors and growers may fall to very low levels. A short crop will usually cause commodity prices to rise, perhaps substantially. Cooperatives may need to ration the short supplies to key industrial and food service customers to whom they sell their commodity as ingredients. Both of these instances represent movement along a demand curve, which should be distinguished from shifting of the demand curve resulting from demand expansion programs. Demand expansion efforts in times of large supplies may include increased food service promotions and extra efforts ‘0 induce industrial food manufacturer customers to expand use of existing products and if POSSible to introduce new products. This relatively undifferentiated commodity market plays a key role in almond supply- demand coordination particularly in regard to the substantial annual supply fluctuations. A key part of Blue Diamond’s strategy involves remaining a reliable supplier not only to bl.2“‘l _10 . w/o Marketing Order Mean=1 .9 30:9 .1 7'2 73 7'4 7'5 76 77 78 7'9 80 8'1 8'2 83 8'4 85 86 Year However, since the supply management provisions were used just five times in 15 194 years, it is more useful to examine impacts in terms of specific years than for the entire period. The simulation indicates that the largest price impacts occurred in 1980 and 1984. The simulation model results suggest that had the marketing order not been implemented in 1980, the f.o.b. price change for frozen cherries and canned cherries (not shown) would have been 12¢(frozen weight) and 10¢(expressed in RPE), respectively. These price differences were 28% and 16% of actual prices in 1980, respectively. Grower prices for raw processing cherries in 1980 would have been lower without the use of the marketing order by an estimated 6¢, which represents a 32% decrease from the actual 20¢ gower price. Change in total gower revenue is another important factor to consider in examining marketing order impacts. Table 25 shows the estimated net change in revenue from using the supply management provisions. The second to the last column shows the net change in gower revenue implied by the changes in prices and quantities sold for frozen and canned cherries in the ”no marketing order" scenario in the simulation. Since frozen and canned cherries represented on average about two thirds of all cherries sold (utilized production) in the period 1972-1986, the revenue figures were adjusted upward to approximate the changes in total revenue that gowers would have received from the sale of all cherry products. The figures in the last column were computed by dividing the previous column (revenue from sales of frozen and canned cherries) by the percentage of total utilized production each year represented by U.S. sales of frozen and carried cherries. The estimated total revenue effect from the simulation of removing tart cherries from the primary market either by reserve pool or secondary market diversion varies from a low of $700,000 in 1975 to a high of $8.2 million in 1980. Since releasing reserve pools into the primary market in years following establishment of reserve pools (and changes in private stocks and sales) generally have an opposite revenue impact from reserve pool storage, looking at pairs of years in terms of net revenue change is also useful. The 195 Tart Cherry Federal Marketing Order, Based on Simulation Model Without Marketing Table 25. Grower Revenue and Net Change in Revenue With and Without With Marketing Order Order Net Change Net Net Grower Change in Grower Change Revenue Supply Revenue in U.S. from Due to from Net Grower Sales of Sales of MO. Sales of Change Revenue Frozen Frozen Opera- Frozen in (adjust- and Grower and tions in Grower and Grower ed for Canned Price Canned Simula— Price Canned Re- utilized Cherries‘ (cents Cherries tion2 (cents Cherries venue produc- Year (mil.lbs.) per lb.) (mil. S) (mil.lbs.) per lb.) (mil. 3) (mil. 3) tion)3 1972 213.3 8.2 17.5 -36.8 6.9 16.0 + 1.5 +1.8 1973 128.9 18.9 24.4 21.9 26.5 ~2.1 -2.8 1974 163.4 18.5 30.2 17.3 32.3 -2.1 -3.4 1975 159.1 102 16.2 8.6 15.8 +05 +0.7 1976 108.8 25.1 27.3 24.6 27.2 +0.1 +0.2 1977 150.6 29.4 44.3 28.8 44.1 +0.2 +0.3 1978 135.2 43.8 592 43.6 59.3 -0.1 «0.2 1979 118.7 472 56 46.8 55.8 +0.2 +0.3 1980 118.5 20.2 23.9 13.8 19.4 +4.5 +8.2 1981 96.5 44.5 42.9 47.8 44.6 -1.7 -2.3 1982 164 14.1 23.1 13.7 22.7 +0.4 +0.6 119.6 46.6 55.7 47.7 56.4 -0.7 -0.9 119.7 25.0 29.9 20.1 26.6 +3.4 +7.2 164.7 22.4 36.9 NS 35.4 + 1.5 +2.6 181.6 20.3 36.9 20.2 36.7 +0.2 0.2 ___ _ _ ’Sales of frozen and canned cherries were chosen as the basis for comparing changes in gower revenue from marketing order implementation, since changes in total utilized farm production were not estimated in the model simulation. 2A negative sign indicates the net quantity removed from the primary markets through use of the federal marketing order. A positive sign indicates quantities released into the primary markets from reserve pool in the year following the establishment of the reserve pool. 3These figures are an approximation of what total revenue changes based on the value of utilized production. They were computed by dividing the previous column by the percentage of total utilized production represented by U.S. sales of frozen and canned cherries. Frozen and canned sales (shown in the first column) are on average approximately 68% of utilized production, ranging from 47% to 83%. 196 estimated marketing order revenue impact of $8.2 million in 1980 is partially offset by an estimated $2.3 million decrease in total revenue in 1981 compared to the situation that would have occurred without using supply management provisions of the marketing order. 6.1.2.2.2. Impact of Using the Tart Cherry Marketing Order in Other Large Crop Years Several other years in the 19803 were potential candidates for supply management actions to mitigate the price-depressing consequences of large crops. Therefore another part of the research involved asking what would have been the price impact had the marketing order been used in those other large crop years of 1982, 1987, and 1989. The reasons for selecting those three years were described above and are briefly restated here. A very large crop and very low price in 1982 were followed by a very short crop and very high prices in 1983. This provided a nearly ideal set of circumstances for using the reserve pool. Although the order was terminated in 1986, it is also worth investigating the potential impact of using the marketing order in 1987 and 1989 had it continued to be a supply management tool available to tart cherry subsector participants. In those two years, supplies were in surplus and were large enough to have had a substantial price-depressing effect which use of the marketing order could have alleviated to a certain extent had the marketing order been available. Table 26 presents hypothetical quantities in a manner analogous to the actual figures in Table 22. Total Production and Fresh Utilization in Table 26 are actual figures, and the Percentage of Production in Controlled Area represents the actual proportion of production in the states that were regulated by the marketing order prior to 1986. Computation of the remaining figures in Table 26 required some judgnent as to what might have happened had the order been in effect. For example, an additional factor in these scenarios is the likelihood of reduced production abandonment if the marketing order had been used. With somewhat higher prices, gowers would likely have been induced to harvest a larger 197 proportion of their crops. Also, industry observers have noted that high processed prices and processor margins have tended to reduce processor perceptions of risk. The reduced perceived risk has encouraged processors to pack larger quantities of tart cherries. Adjustments in supply were therefore included inithe simulation to provide a more realistic picture in terms of actual supply changes. The likely reduction in production abandonment that would occur if the marketing order had been used was accounted for by reducing non-marketing order abandonment by 50% (1982--from 23.0 to 11.5; 1989--12.0 to 6.0). This is shown in the third row of Table 26. The difference between total abandonment and non-harvest diversion is called non-market order abandonment (or open market abandonment). Estimated non-harvest diversion figures, based on past experience with crops of comparable size, appear in the bottom row of Table 26. Concomitantly, estimated total production would have been higher by 11.5 and 6.0 million pounds in 1982 and 1989, respectively, due to less abandonment of the cherry crop. The estimated changes in production figures appear in column (6) of Table 27. These adjustments in figures make the simulation somewhat more realistic. The next step in the computation was Subtracting Non-Marketing Order Abandonment and Fresh Utilization from Total Production yields New Crop for Processing, just as was done to compute the comparable figures in Table 22 for the simulation of the five actual marketing order implementations between 1972 and 1985. Computation of Restricted Tonnage was done in the same manner as in Table 22, and the Restricted Percentages used (20%, 25% and 10%) were based on the Recommended Marketing Policy of the Cherry Administrative Board. In 1986, the CAB ageed on target restricted percentages for crops of various sizes."2 The estimated restricted tonnage figures for 1982, 1987, and 1989 were 55.7, 68.6 and 21.5 million pounds, respectively. ”'Backgound Economic Analysis and 1986 Marketing Policy of Cherry Administrative Board,” May 1986. 198 Table 26. Determination and Uses of Restricted Tonnage Under Simulation of Tart Cherry Federal Marketing Order 1982 1987 1989 Total Production 310.9 358.5 264.1 - Fresh Utilization 7.4 9.0 6.7 - Non-market order abandonment 11.5 41.0 6.0 = New Crop for Processing 292.0 308.5 251.4 X Restricted Percentage 20% 25% 10% = Restricted Tonnage Estimate 58.4 77.1 25.1 X Percentage of Production in 95.3 89.0 85.6 Controlled Area = Restricted Tonnage in 55.7 68.6 21.5 Controlled Area L Sum of Marketing Order Uses = 55.7 68.6 21.5 Reserve Pool 42.7 0 0 + Secondary Market Diversion 0 37.8 12.4 + Non-harvest Diversion The next step in the process of estimating the figures to use to represent marketing order supply management for 1982, 1987 and 1989 was to make judgnents about how gowers would have chosen to use various provisions of the tart cherry marketing order.”3 In the early 19803, secondary market diversion provisions still had not been used, so the uses of restricted tonnage would likely have been the reserve pool and non-harvest diversion. The non-harvest diversion tonnage was estimated at 13.0 million pounds based on prior experience with a crop of that magnitude; the remaining 42.7 million pounds would have been put into the reserve pool. In 1987 and 1989, on the other hand, all of the tonnage that was not destined for non-harvest diversion would likely have ended up in secondary market ”Estimates were supplied by Dr. Donald J. Ricks, former chair and economic advisor to the CAB. 199 diversion. Since the late 19803 was a period of general overproduction, the reserve pool option was no longer viable. Table 27 shows the estimated quantities that might have been removed from the market and subsequently released or diverted in the operation of the marketing order. The Table 27. Simulation of Tart Cherry Federal Marketing Order Implementation in 1982, 1987, and 1989: Impact on Frozen f.o.b. and Grower Price ’This scenario assumes that 10.7 mill. pounds (25% of the 1982-83 pool) would be released in spring 1983, but would have an impact on prices equal to one third of the actual tonnage. The release variable RPR is therefore set equal to 3.6. 1983 reserve carryin thus equals 39.1. (-42.7+3.6=-39.1) 2 The assumption is made that if the marketing order is used, open market abandonment would be half of what actually occurred without the marketing order in 1982 and 1989, but that in 1987 Open market abandonment would have been the same without the order. Thus Open market abandonment declines in this scenario by the following amounts: (a) 1982, 23.0 to 11.5, (b) 1989, 12.0 to 6.0. In the simulation, total production in 1982 and 1989 increases by 11.5 and 6.0 million pounds, respectively. Change l M.O. Sec- Net in l Re- on- Change Prod. l Re- lease dary Non- in due to Frozen . serve Fi- Mar- Har- Supply re- f.o.b. i Pool gure ket vest due to duced price Ton- Used Di- Diver- MD. in Aban- impact Grower 1 ‘ nage ver- sion Simu- don- (froz. price l Year RPSA RPR sion QNHD Iation ment’ wt.) impact l (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (3) (9) g 1982‘ 42.7 +3.6 -13.0 -55.7 + 115 + 12.7 +6.3 . 19831 +391 +391 -175 -129 1 w 1984 0 + 1.8 + 1.2 I 1985 0 -o.7 .04 . 1986 0 NC NC . l 1987 -37.8 -30.8 -68.6 0 + 7.2 + 2.7 , l , 1988 0 + 1.8 -1.0 , ‘ 1989 -124 -9.1 21.5 +6.0 +23 +1.1 1 200 fifth column shows the tonnage used in the simulation to represent the net change in supply from the operation of the marketing order. As Table 27 indicates, the estimated price increases per pound from using the marketing order in 1982, 1987, and 1989 are approximately six cents, three cents and one cent, respectively, representing 40%, 35% and 5% increases over actual gower prices. Another notable result is that had the marketing order been used in 1982-83, the average gower price would have declined by an estimated 11¢ (25%) from the high 1983 price of 47¢ per pound due to release of the 1982 reserve to supplement the short supplies. The crop size in 1983 was 83% of average shipments for the previous four years. The almond marketing order is examined next. The final section of this chapter applies various performance criteria to the tart cherry marketing order analysis and compares these results to almond and raisin marketing order analyses. 6.2. Almond Marketing Order Simulation An additional goal of this research project was to analyze the impact (especially the impact on gower prices) of implementing the reserve provision of the federal marketing order for almonds. The modeling approach is similar to that used for simulating the tart cherry marketing order. The price impact is estimated by comparing actual season average prices with prices estimated in an econometric model that simulates prices and quantities over the period 1973-1989 if the marketing order had not been used. In the ten year period 1980.1989, the almond reserve was implemented seven times. The main hypothesis of this analysis is that almond prices would have been lower than actual prices were with the use of the marketing order if the almond supply management progam had not been implemented in certain high production years. The mOdel simulates the historical period 1973-1989, assuming in an alternative scenario that the l'tt‘Bi'rerve. was not implemented in any year during that period. The price difference between 201 Table 28. Variable Identification: Almond Model I Variable Definition ll A. ENDOGENOUS VARIABLES II ACRES Bearing acres (trees 4 years or older), thousands) II DOMSAL U.S. domestic almond sales, millions of pounds FOBPR Handler f.o.b. price, dollars per pound (opening f.o.b. price of CAGE/Blue Diamond) GRPR Grower price, dollars per pound PROD Total U.S. almond production, millions of pounds B. COMPUTED VARIABLES REDMARK Quantity redetermined marketable (subtracting computed losses from total production), millions of pounds; estimated at fixed rate of 95% of total production FREEQ Free tonnage remaining after almond reserve implementation, millions of pounds (REDMARK - RESERVE) PGAV3 Three year moving average of gower prices (GRPR) lagged 4, 5, and 6 years, dollars per pound TOTSUP Total salable supply, millions of pounds (CI + FREEQ + RELEASE) C. EXOGENOUS VARIABLES CI Carryin almond stocks, millions of pounds CO Carryout almond stocks, millions of pounds ID Personal disposable income, billions of dollars I RELEASE Quantity released from almond reserve under federal marketing order, millions of pounds RESERVE Quantity set aside in almond reserve under federal marketing order, millions of pounds TRND Trend, 1973 = 73, etc. T81 Dummy variable (equals 0 before 1981, 1 thereafter) WPRIC Farm price of walnuts, cents per pound d YIELD Almond yield, pounds per acre Note: In the tables showing estimated equations, variables with an L prefix were estimated in log form. 202 actual prices and the simulated ”no reserve" prices is the estimated impact of using various supply management provisions of the marketing order. 6.2.1. The Almond Model The econometric equations and related computations that make up the model are presented below. There are three equations estimated econometrically as single equations by OLS. Domestic almond demand is modeled as a simultaneous system and estimated by three stage least squares. Variables are identified in Table 28. 6.2.1.1. The Estimated Equations The first step in modeling almond production was to estimate almond gower supply response. Similar to the approach taken for the tart cherry model, almond acreage supply response was based on a simple average of several years of lagged gower prices and bearing acres lagged one year. Since 1973 a bearing tree has been defined as four years or older; Table 29. Bearing Acreage Equation Estimated by OLS Variable Dependent Variable fl label ACRES (Eq. #1) Constant 29.0361 (4.29) PGAV3 38.7000 (5.41) ACRES(T-1) .8434 R2=.994 Adj. R2=.983 ___________ f _____#n ____+_ _. _._J T-statistics appear in parentheses to the right of each coefficient. OLS estimate was corrected for serial correlation with Cochrane-Orcutt autoregessive procedure. hr 203 the independent variable for gower price (PGAV3) was therefore defined as the average of gower prices (T-4) through (T-6). The estimated coefficients are presented in Table 29. Yield was considered exogenous, and acreage times yield equals production. The next step was to estimate almond demand equations. Similar to the situation in developing the tart cherry model, the assumption was made that since all data are annual, domestic demand could be most effectively modeled as a system in which domestic sales and domestic handler price are simultaneously determined. In the two-equation demand model, handler price was estimated as function of domestic sales (LDOMSAL), the price of a key substitute (walnutsuLWPRIC), and personal disposable income (LID). The L prefix Table 30. Domestic Almond Demand Estimated by Three Stage Least Squares Dependent Variables Explanatory i Variables LDOMSAL (Eq. #2) l LFOBPR (Eq. #4) Constant .4422 (-1.29) -3.6213 (.-2 71) l LFOBPR .0117 (.09) l LTOTSUP .4687 (5.28) ' LDOMSAL(T-1) .4993 (3.51) l ' LDOMSAL , LWPRIC LID l T81 l 7 7 7 — ———————— —-- —— —— +—+ R2= .945 l , Adj. R2= .910 ,~ | D.W.= 1.75 l T-statistics appear in parentheses to the right of each estimated coefficient. An L prefix indicates estimation in log form. 204 indicates estimation in log form. An additional variable was added to capture the shift in the supply-demand balance in the early 19803. After a period of strong demand expansion in the 19703 in which no reserves were implemented for eight years, reserves began to be implemented every year in the early 19803. A time shift dummy variable (T81) was thus included in the demand equation. Domestic sales were modeled as a function of f.o.b. price, total supply, and lagged domestic sales. The f.o.b. price variable was not statistically sigrificant, but was nevertheless retained because of the theoretical justification that price should influence quantity sold. Interviews with almond handlers indicated that almond gower prices are a residual of f.o.b. handler prices after the processor margin has been subtracted. Grower prices were therefore modeled as a function only of handler prices. Table 31. Almond Grower Price Equation Estimated by OLS V . ll Explanatory DePendent arrable Variables GRPR (Eq. #4) II Constant -.1519 1 (-3.46) FOBPR . R2=.936 l Adj. R2=.936 D.W. = 2.67 T-statistics appear in parentheses to the right of each coefficient. The final equation needed to complete the system is an equation to predict export sales. A demand model incorporating elements of foreig1 demand for California almonds, and accounting for exchange rates in various foreig1 markets was beyond the scope of this research. Since this model was for historical simulation purposes only with emphasis on changes in the domestic market, a simpler export sales equation was developed. 205 Table 32. Export Sales Equation Estimated by OLS I Explanatory Dependent Variable Variables LEXPSAL (Eq. #5) Constant -3.2180 (-3.86) LPROD .6443 (6.76) LC] .1076 (1.84) LFOBPR -.0971 (-.73) TRND .0550 (3.27) T81 -.2995 (-3.25) R2=.975 Adj. R2=.947 D.W. = 3.21 T-statistics appear in parentheses to the right of each coefficient. An L prefix indicates log form estimation. Independent variables included total almond production, carryin stocks, f.o.b. price, a trend variable, and a dummy variable that represented the shift in the supply-demand balance that began in the early 19803. Estimated coefficients are presented in Table 32. 6.2.1.2. Full Model and Solution Process This section presents the full model, which links the five econometrically estimated equations and the identities. The model carries out dynamic sequential predictions of the endogenous variables. Below is an overview of how the blocks fit together to carry out the sequential computations. 6.2.1.2.1. Overview of Almond Econometric Model BLOCK 1. BEARING ACREAGE, PRODUCTION AND QUANTITY REDETERMINED MARKETABLE [Supply response in terms of bearing acreage is based on a three-year moving average of lagged gower prices, (T-4) through (T-6). Yield is exogenous and acreage times yield equals production. Quantity Redetermined Marketable is equal to 95% of production.] 206 BLOCK II. CARRYIN, SEASONAL SUPPLY, AND MARKETING ORDER IMPLEMENTATION [Seasonal supply is equal to carryin stocks plus the quantity redetermined marketable. Total salable supply is less than the seasonal supply by the quantity set aside in the marketing order reserve. The quantity of almonds set aside in the reserve (RESERVE) and the quantity released in subsequent years (RELEASE) are exogenous variables] BLOCK III. U.S. DOMESTIC ALMOND DEMAND [Estimates f.o.b. almond prices and domestic consumption (delivered sales). A two- equation simultaneous system is solved by three stage least squares and reduced form equations are used for dynamic sequential forecasts] BLOCK IV. GROWER PRICE [Grower price is predicted from a regession of f.o.b price. A moving average of lagged gower prices is used in estimating bearing acreage in Block 1.] BLOCK V. EXPORT SALES AND CARRYOUT [Export sales are estimated and carryout is calculated as a residual by subtracting domestic and export sales from total salable supply]. 6.2.1.2.2. Model Structure Showing Equations and Solution Process One loop of the model (Step A through Step L) calculates values for each variable for one year. A DO LOOP restarts the calculations for each succeeding year. The numbered equations are the econometrically estimated equations presented above. The coefficients are represented by the letter a,. The remainder are computations (identities) based on the estimated variables. Verbal descriptions appear above the variable names for most equations. Ittt$tttittttttttttttttt#883833*****¥¥*#***$#*#¥#t8t¥¥t¥¥¥¥¥Ctt¥¥$¥¥¥$$¥¥¥¥$¥t DOT =1973T01989 BLOCK l. BEARING ACREAGE, PRODUCTION AND QUANTITY REDETERMINED MARKETABLE A. Compute 3-year moving average of lagged grower prices = PGAV3 a (GRPRCH)+GRPR(T-5)+GRPR(I’-6)) + 3 B. Bearing = con- lagged average acreage stant + a, bearing + a2 lagged acreage price (#1) ACRES = con- + a,ACRES(T-1) + azPGAVS stant 207 C. PROD = ACRES X YIELD D. REDMARK = PROD X 0.95 BLOCK II. CARRYIN, SEASONAL SUPPLY, AND MARKETING ORDER IMPLEMENTATION E. Carryin = Carryout(T-1) CI -- CO (T -1) F. Free quantity tonnage = redetermined - quantity in marketable reserve FREEQ = REDMARK - RESERVE G. Total quantity salable released supply = carryin + free + from tonnage reserve TOTSUP = CI + FREEQ + RELEASE BLOCK III. U.S. DOMESTIC ALMOND DEMAND H. Domestic constant - handler total lagged sales = a, f.o.b. + a2 salable + a3 domestic price supply sales (#2) LDOMSAL = constant - a,LFOBPR + azLTOTSUP + a,LDOMSAL(T-1) I. Handler dispos- f.o.b. = con- a, domestic a, walnut a3 able + a4 dummy price stant - sales - price + income variable (#3)LFOBPR = con- a,LDOMSAL - a2LWPRIC + a,LID - a,T81 stant - BLOCK IV. GROWER PRICE .1. Grower price = handler constant + a, f.o.b. price (#4) GRPR = constant + a,FOBPR BLOCK V. EXPORT SALES AND CARRYOUT handler K. Export con- + a, produc- a2 carry- a,f.o.b. + a,trend - a, dummy sales = stant tion + In + price variable (#5)EXPSAL= con- + a,PROD + a2CI - a,FOBPR + a,TRND - a5T81 stant L carryout = total salable - domestic - supply sales CO = TOTSUP - DOMSAL - END DO T 208 export sales EXPSAL ****************t*tit*ttt*tttttfi*1!t********************t*********** 6.2.1.3. Model Performance Table 33 shows goodness-of-fit measures for dynamic sequential predictions of variables over the period 1973-1989. The model appears to provide quite good estimates of the first four variables in that table, all of which have a mean absolute percentage error Table 33. Goodness-of-f‘it Measures for Dynamic Sequential Predictions of Almond Model Variables, 1973-1989 r.__.= Mean Root Mean of Mean Abso- Absolute Vari- Square lute Percent- . able Error Error age Error * (M) (RMSE) (MAE) (MAPE) l Bearing Acres, thousands (ACRES) 333.1 9.4 7.8 2.3 Total Production, mill. lbs. (PROD) 357.1 10.3 8.3 2.3 Quantity redetermined marketable, 336.9 9.9 8.6 2.3 million lbs. (REDMARK) Total salable supply, million lbs. 426.7 15.0 18.6 3.5 (TOTSUP) I Domestic sales, mill. lbs. (DOMSAL) 112.5 . 7.8 6.6 7.8 I Export sales, million lbs. (EXPSAL) 208.5 19.2 7.0 Carryout stocks, mill. lbs. (CO) 105.7 15.0 F.O.B. price, 3 per lb. 1.43 .22 Grower price, 3 per lb. 209 of 3.5% or less. Those four variables are all related to the supply of almonds -- (1) acreage, (2) production, (3) the portion of production that is redetermined marketable after culled almonds are removed, and (4) total salable supply. Estimates of domestic and export almond sales are off by an average of 7%, and estimated carryout differs from its actual value by an average of 17%. Estimated f.o.b. prices and gower prices for almonds differ from their actual historical values by an average of 19¢ (14%) and 18¢ (17%), respectively. Those errors in prediction are somewhat high for key variables. The results presented here were nevertheless superior to various alternative models, so the model specification presented herein was used for the analysis of almond marketing order price impacts. The model results were judged to be adequate for historical simulation purposes. 6.2.2. Simulated Alternative Scenario: Non-implementation of Almond Reserve The model carries out dynamic sequential predictions of gower and handler prices as well as quantities of almonds produced and consumed over the period 1973-1989. Price impacts of the almond reserve are measured by comparing actual prices to prices estimated in an alternative scenario in which reserve pools are not implemented. If the almond order had not been in effect, reserves could not have been established and all harvested almonds would have to be sold into domestic or international markets or end up as carryover stocks at the end of the season. The increased seasonal supply of almonds (relative to historical levels) in the simulated "no reserve" scenario is hypothesized to result in lower simulated grower and handler prices than occurred historically. Just as with the tart cherry simulation, the magritude of the price change is the value in terms of increased gower prices of using the almond reserve. 210 6.2.2.1. Method of Analysis The exogenous variable RESERVE in the model represents the quantity of almonds set aside in the reserve. In most years reserve almonds were diverted to non-competitive outlets. However, in 1988 and 1989, reserve almonds were released into the primary market. The quantities released in those two years are represented by the exogenous variable RELEASE. In the base run, RESERVE and RELEASE are set equal to their actual values (see steps F. and G. in Block II. of the ”Almond Model Structure Showing Equations and Solution Process" in Appendix B). In the scenario representing non- implementation of the reserve, the values of RESERVE and RELEASE are set equal to zero, resulting in a higher seasonal supply of almonds in the alternative scenario compared to the base run for those years in which a reserve was declared. Although the almond federal marketing order has been in effect since 1950, no reserves were established between 1973 and 1979. Simulation over a ten year period in the 19803 was judged to be sufficient to demonstrate the dynamic price impact of not implementing the order. 6.2.2.2. Estimated Price Impacts Without Marketing Order Implementation Reserves were implemented in seven of the ten years between 1980 and 1989. In five of those seven years, all of the reserve almonds were diverted to non-competitive outlets. However, in 1988 and 1989 all of the reserve almonds were released onto commercial markets the following year, as shown in column 4 of Table 34. Columns 1 through 4 of Table 34 show the historical record of reserve percentages and associated almond quantities placed in reserve. Columns 5 through 7 present estimates of changes in almond quantities that would have occurred in the absence of reserves (changes in carryin stocks, total salable supply, and domestic sales). Columns 8 through 10 show the historical gower prices and the estimated 211 downs—coca :22 55 3.5.: Ca gong—83%. 3238 208 e mm 523 6582—38 105E363. banana 2: m. Seaman—cu 05 was cocoa—coca Bo... Banana 2 2E. A. .30. BEA—E8. ma 8 autumn: .20 5:26 Loom owe—5v 8 26 3:3 a. mob Bo: no be: b.2300. __ n. m+ one. + 8. a So. 3. S». N 8... no -.§ 3: o o e: .5 SE . _ cdm- new: 34 No.33 3de e363 came: 3H4: mm 503% $3 _ «awn- vmmr SA www.mvfi Sada Nnme c @363 mu wwménc 53 3:. was me; Swfiw mmeNH 9.0mm c c c 306mm 33 12. v9: cw. coed. $8.3 SEN o 8.4.3. S @894. 33 we- 2b.- R. wSHm need the c «3.3 m Roficn ewe“ v.7 ever x: 32H mmed ~86 c v3.0 m Sham mweu Wm- e8: we. and ooh.“ SCH a Bed N $5.8m $3 54. So: we. _ comm m8; cad c o c vmfidwm $3 m4- :8: 53 m3. o :5.» c _ c n36 N cemncm 83 __ .582— .£ can mam—.8. menace com—=8 38.—om .338 a: C C C 5 3 5 C 8 S» SE Boa 8E 2:83— otomom 9:83— 9:39: 9:83. 0233— via _ .6320 9:83. 8390 _ 255—3 2855» 5223 EC: 3 Coca—con— coct“; W ~ .953. 5923 Race. bee—am 33w 962m woman—om coca—m owe BEE H _ Cc omo oweaau 03.2mm “58800 nub—Leo 555:0 3:550 -Eouuom Luau—com L .385.“ out; Eek E 09:30 E mecca—(4 m a me 8390 m E omega 3383mm 09:30 7 Ca V" oweaao 3.2:th _ vofificmm— v22: 4 555.5 . 3: L -umm— T llll ll -|l-- ll: - lll:||1ll ac:8.em8£efi~ .com. chewed $3 .83 dosage—038m EEO .wazoe—Laz vac—=2 505$» 3§l_lo .35.— v.5. 5:530. vegan—Emu .3 03am. 212 price changes that would have occurred based on the simulation if reserves had not been established. Columns 9 and 10 are some of the key results of the analysis. The simulation results indicate that without the reserve, both f.o.b. and grower prices would have declined relative to their historical level for each year between 1980 and 1989 (however, only grower price changes are shown in Table 34). Estimates of price decreases range from 2c in 1980 (a year in which only a small reserve was declared) to 33¢ in 1987, a heavy production year in which a large quantity of almonds had been placed in reserve. These estimates of price decreases in the absence of the order can also be considered as the price impact of using the reserve as a supply management tool. Without the ability to set aside in a reserve a portion of almonds produced in a heavy production year, total salable supply would increase. The "no reserve” simulation results also indicate that increased almond quantities in the primary market and lower prices also bring about other changes, including higher domestic sales, export sales, and carryout stocks. In the simulation, the higher ending stocks in the absence of a reserve in one year in turn have a price depressing effect in the subsequent year by increasing carryin stocks and consequently total salable supply for that year. For example, in 1985 a 10% reserve was established by the Almond Board of California, resulting in 44 million pounds being placed in reserve. Season average grower price with the reserve was 80¢ per pound. The "no reserve" simulation suggests that without a reserve, the average grower price would have been 10¢ lower (a 70¢ price), due largely to the increase in total salable supply of 71 million pounds. Associated with the lower price in the simulation results were a domestic sales increase of 10.7 million pounds (column 7) and increased export sales of 7 million pounds (not shown in Table 34). However, the increased supply in the simulation resulted in a 53 million pound increase in carryover stocks (which appears as carryover stocks for 1986 in column 5). This increase in carryover 213 raised total salable supply in 1986, a short crop year in which no reserve was needed. This additional carryover would have decreased average grower price by an estimated 26¢ in 1986. Note, however, that this large simulated price decrease in 1986 was from a record high actual price of $1.92 per pound. The estimated percentage price decrease from the simulation in both 1985 and 1986 was around 13% (column 10). Estimated changes in total salable supply in 1985 and 1986 were 11.5% and 14.1%, respectively. The situation is more complicated for 1988 and 1989. Large reserves were established in both 1987 and 1988 due to unusually heavy production in both years. Almond Board records indicate that portions of these reserves were released in the same marketing year (not shown in Table 34). The remainder of the reserve in each case was released into the primary market in the following year rather than diverting the almonds to non- competitive outlets as had been done in earlier years. In the ”no reserve” scenario, there would have been neither an almond reserve nor a release, and the estimates of the simulated net effect for 1987 and 1988 were grower price decreases of 33¢ and 27¢, respectively, due to increases in total salable supply in the simulation of 142 million and 122 million pounds. Actual and simulated almond grower prices are compared graphically in Figure 42. As Table 34 indicated, "no reserve” prices were lower in each year of the simulation. The analysis suggests that, considering the whole period, prices would have averaged 8c lower without the order (mean prices were $1.08 versus $0.96). The graph also illustrates the simulation result that the marketing order dampened steep price declines in 1987 and 1988. However, overall variability would have been about the same. Changes in total grower revenue attributable to the almond reserve is another key consideration. Table 35 shows estimates of changes in revenue based on the simulated price changes. Only small reserves (2-3%) were used during the period 1980-1983. The reserves in those years were created mainly for market development purposes. The ABC policy was 214 Figure 42. Comparison of Actual Almond Grower Price to Simulated Price Without Reserve 2 1.3 4 Actual Price Mean=$1.08 $D=0.34 “a g 1 6 q Simulated Price without a. ' Marketing Order 3 Mean=$0.96 $020.32 a 1 .4 - 4A 2'? '1' 1.2 ‘ a. b 3 1~ L O 0.8 r / 0.6 I I T I 7 I T I I I T 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 Year to set aside specific quantities to sell at reduced prices to food manufacturers that were in the process of developing new almond-based food products. The model results indicate that although grower prices were increased through use of the marketing order, the higher quantities that would have been sold in the absence of the order would have generated slightly higher total grower revenue than was obtained with the order. Simulation results indicated that use of the order reduced total grower income in specific years between 1980 and 1983 by amounts ranging from $600,000 to $3.3 million (0.2% and 1% of actual grower revenue, respectively). With larger reserves beginning in 1984, however, the revenue impact became strongly positive, with net gains in grower revenue of between $17 million in 1984 (4% increase) and $117 million in 1987 (18% increase). The largest estimated decline occurred in 1986, $27 million (6%). This result occurred because in the "no marketing order” scenario simulated 215 Table 35. Estimated Grower Revenue With and Without the Almond Marketing Order Reserve Esti- l mated Change Net in Total Change Grower Total Salable Grower Total in Total Total Price Revenue Supply Price Revenue Revenue ; Sales with with Without without without with i (mil. MD. MD. Reserve M.O. M.O. M.O. l Year lbs.) ($/lb.) (mil. $) (mil. lb.) ($/lb.) (mil. $) (mil. S) l 1980 305.1 1.47 448.6 6.1 1.45 451.3 -2.7 ll 1981 383.1 0.78 298.8 5.2 0.77 297.8 1.0 1982 330.8 0.94 310.9 9.3 0.92 311.5 -0.6 1983 221.8 1.04 230.7 13.6 0.99 234.0 -3.3 d 1984 562.7 0.77 433.2 37.2 0.69 416.3 17.0 I 1985 444.0 0.80 355.2 71.4 0.70 358.7 -3.5 l 1986 235.7 1.92 452.5 52.8 1.66 479.5 -26.9 I 1987 634.6 1.00 634.6 142.5 0.67 517.5 117.0 1988 546.5 1.05 573.9 122 0.78 519.4 54.4 1989 457.2 1.02 466.3 —85.6 0.98 365.6 100.7 l by the model, the private carryover stocks and overall sales would have been higher and the price substantially lower leading to increased revenue relative to the actual historical record. As indicated previously, the 1986 experience with shortages and very high prices led to a shift in Almond Board policy, in which certain quantities could be retained in a reserve pool to be released in subsequent years in case of a shortage, rather than diverting all of the reserve to secondary market uses. This policy was applied in 1987-1989. Large crops in 1987 and 1988 led to Almond Board to declare reserves of 18% and 25%, respectively. The 1987 reserve was released in 1988, but since the crop was again large, an even larger reserve (25%) was declared. When 1989 turned out to be a short crop year relative to prior years, 216 the entire remaining reserve was released, thus providing the stabilizing effect for which it was intended. The simulation results indicated that without this stabilizing effect, grower price would have been slightly higher (approximately 4c higher or a 4% increase over the the actual price). However, the substantial extra supplies led to larger sales in 1989 than would have occurred in the absence of the order, yielding a net grower revenue increase of $100 million. After the following section on the raisin marketing order, the three marketing order analyses are compared using several performance criteria. 6.3. Raisin Marketing Order Simulation The purpose of this section is to describe the results of the 1991 French and Nuckton (FN) study of the economic impact of the federal marketing order for raisins. In the next section, comparisons are made with the foregoing tart cherry and almond simulation results. FN used an econometric simulation model to estimate the potential impacts on prices and revenue if there had been no reserve pool operations under a federal marketing order. The tart cherry and almond simulation models examined earlier in this chapter were based in part on the FN approach. Both the tart cherry and almond simulations involved comparison of a single alternative ”no reserve" scenario with the historical record of prices, and quantities, and revenues which were influenced by use of reserves in large-crop years under the respective marketing orders. FN’s approach involved a number of different scenarios. FN generated nine different scenarios to analyze a range of possible impacts with the different economic environment that would exist without a marketing order. Their main assumption was that risk perceptions on the part of raisin grape growers would alter two specific behavioral responses. First, the higher risk environment that would exist without the stabilizing effect of the marketing order would bring forth reduced planting responses. 217 Figure 43. Mean Grower Prices for Grapes for Drying, 1964-1985 Actual and Alternative Scenarios Based on French and Nuckton Simulation 1(=9 ISinS Higher K means more grapes utilized for crush and ewer dried for re 1v913......0.0......0..3..0........ ..0.033%?Q3309€¢€¢.9@%0e€..%£33@. /\t \r‘ \r\r t\t 000.0000.000000.000...000000000. l 8..........,.......0...........0..0....... . (\1 r\/\ .0.....000...00.00.000.000000000100. .0....0.....3060090..©...30 ...®€0.0.o..3@?..€9z€€00¢c0 3%.....0..0.....9330...o®%. ..93...0..0..0.093900.000.. 20000000.000.000.00000000000 000.0...000.....000/000000 \I\ \I\I\ 0000.00.00.0000000000. nbsb©©00..00.0....o©.a@@€ 000.00.000.000000000... 2000.00.0000..000000000000 4.......0........0.0.00000000....0... «@309939z.0...........0.z€¢ ...z0..0....0......0....... @3..9.0...0.0.............. 2.00.0.000000000000000.0000... (J. @.€...00e0..0.0.00.0. .0.?3.0.....000.0.93. ...z.....0..000.00330 Ru 3%....00..0000..0.... _ 7.0....000..0.0...00... 0.000000000000000 93.....0009.ec.€ Cu...0.00.......9&z ...........os@.3. 95......0.00....... no .0....0.0.0.3b.0..0..0 ......0.....00.0.3... .0 i... 0.00.0...00933 .0.....0..0000..0..@% 9500€€.0000909i000.0000. .0.!0000.0..@3.. ..0.....0....... ..oz.......9.... .....bob0..00.9. 9.é....90. 000...... K 7 19 47 F H145 2.9.0.9...0 00.0.0003 ..093@z..0. .0.%..00... 750......0... .0.!0Q00330093z. .0.....00000930 ..00003%3%9300.0 0....0..0..3333 2.000000000000000 d U c A 300 290 a a . T O O O 8 7 6 2 2 2 240 a 230 - u o 5 2 .2.» 8a « iota .0320 50: S1 S2 S3 S1 S2 S3 S2 $3 S1 82, 53 are reduced planting scenarios Figure 44. Mean Grower Net Revenue, Grapes for Drying and Crush, 1964-1985: Actual and Alternative Scenarios Based on French and Nuckton Simulation K=9 .:..309.... ... 0...... 0. .0. .0.... 0 0 6 .H H.“ A.” H.” ,. t. o .3 H.“ A... .. r.\ r.\ I.\ l.\ .0.: .\ .\\. 1‘. .\ r.\ 000000000... 033936.000. W0. .0. ,0. ,0. ,0. :0 .0 :0 ..0 0. ,0. ,0. .0. 10.10” .,..0 “H0... 0 . ,0. .0. .0. ,0. «0. ,0. .0 0 .10 .........:0000000000 f0.301.330 ”.00..”20000 /\/\1\ .,...........0000000. K=8 ,0. ..0.. r... .,0 .0.. 0. 0 0 ,.0 0. .0. .0. .0 0333330000.03 1" I. t.\ 4" l.\t \H. :. 1.x I.“ “Ox 1.\ 1.. I. .\ /. t.‘ I.‘ l.\ I.“ 1.\ \\. :. “.0 I.\ 1.\ (.\ 0000000000000 090.... \00/ \z~/\ 00....000 ..0000..0.0000@3 .3€€c00€£330.033 20.0.0.3... \;.I .1x zxr.txl\o\r 0.00000000000000 12 .7. can « £030 use .to .520”. coo: —12 $2 $3 $1 $2 $3 $2 $3 $1 $2, $3 are reduced planting scenarios S1 218 Thus 81 in Figure 43 and Figure 44 represents a scenario in which the planting response is unchanged from the planting equation which FN determined best represented the actual historical situation. In the alternative scenarios $2 and $3, the coefficient on the planting equation in the FN simulation model is reduced to represent planting response reductions of 20% and 40%, respectively, due to the higher risk perceived by growers. Note that the bar in Figure 43 representing mean grower price for the SI scenario ($248) corresponds to Figure 45 below, which compares the SI scenario to actual grower price for the period 1964- 1985. Similarly, the bar representing 83 (mean grower price of $266) in Figure 43 corresponds to Figure 47. The other behavioral change that FN thought should be accounted for was that in a higher risk environment without a marketing order, growers would choose to send somewhat higher proportions of their raisin-type grapes to crush, which before the early 19803 represented a steadier market, and would dry a somewhat smaller proportion to sell as raisins. In Figure 43 and Figure 44, higher levels of K mean that in the equation that allocated grapes between the raisin and crush markets, the coefficient is adjusted to represent a "tilt" toward sending a greater proportion to crush. Thus the three levels of planting response and three levels of raisin versus crush allocation resulted in nine scenarios. The scenario most comparable to the tart cherry and almond analyses above is represented by the bar (81, K=7) showing a price of $248 per ton in Figure 43 and negative net revenue of $9 in Figure 44. A key result of the FN analysis is that for every scenario but the first (81, K=7, with a price of $248 per ton), the lower level of bearing acreage devoted to producing raisins resulted in higher raisin prices relative to the historical record (an average of $255 per ton) when the whole period was considered (1964-1985). However, FN also note that another performance measure, grower net return, accounts for grower sales into both the raisin and crush markets, since many growers typically sold in both markets prior to the reduced 219 availability of the crush outlet in the 19805. Figure 44 shows that historically the average net return was near zero for the entire period, but that six out of nine of the alternative scenarios yielded negative net revenue. Only in the case of a severely reduced planting response (S=3; 40% lower) was production low enough to yield higher net grower returns, combining grapes sold for drying and grapes sold for crush. Note that the bar in Figure 44 representing mean grower net revenue for the SI scenario (-$9) corresponds to Figure 46 below, which compares the SI scenario to actual grower net revenue for the period 1964- 1985. Similarly, the bar representing S3 (mean grower net revenue of $3) in Figure 44 corresponds to Figure 48. To provide further detail on the FN simulation results, prices and returns from two scenarios are presented graphically (SI and S3, K=7). Figure 45 compares actual grower prices for grapes for drying with prices estimated in S] (no reduction in planting response). Figure 46 compares actual and simulated net returns for the same situation. Simulated prices without a marketing order in 81 are both lower on average and more variable, with a standard deviation of prices of 3129 versus 398 for the actual prices. Figure 45 shows that the most significant price stabilizing effects occurred in the 19608 and the 19803. The marketing order prevented steep price declines in 1965-66 and 1982-85. Recall from Chapter 2 that the rapid decline in the availability of the crush outlet led to a sharp increase in raisin production increase during the 19803. The marketing order was used to a considerably lesser degree in the 1970s since prices and returns were higher due to stronger demand for raisins. Comparable results for the S3 scenario are presented in Figure 47 and Figure 48. Prices and net revenue are higher without a marketing order in this scenario due to the assumption of a 40% reduction in grower planting response due to the higher risk associated With a less stable market for raisins. Mean price in S3 rises by $11, and net revenue rises from an average of zero to an average of 33. Also, the reduced planting response in this 220 60» » fin» NbcricrnthNh 00“»WN> “phi Oph- ‘Pop ”mk‘hm 0°“- row—I 3n to em cuss: \53 :2 32 87 r Q99? on... .30 e. nus... .8. Ea... 3. 385m 0 In I o (no; you: ”(1 g) union in" semen 8:23. 955.: e833. asap 2:352 32...? 3.3.... an .253. .530 can b: 3 530: «oz .83qu .3. P5»...— .80» 00 no on on on Va «5 on no on co ans... .3 3.. n5... SE .83 E 1 O O N O O Q o o m (up; you: sad 3) salad mug fl 0 O In .2 u .3 ..m .3" 5.x e .86 8...; 59...; 8.... 33.5”... com 3:33. 95.3: ‘82:: 5.3 E: :95 «5.3.52 .3... 83:35 E: .33. .8...— ..2.Ec 2.20 525. .9. 25: a.) .u «a on a. on .5 N. o. a. a. .u >>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>>> OONI of. e 0 3"}. 2m case: M .5... .2 .83 8.. m \ 70ml W .t 81...... .a mans... 82.8.2 + OO—Q m . 22w » ) $8M sew \ a. a. 13.3 Suns... .8... laggitilra 8. §_§_ 5.5 9.29.52 235.3 essaém E... .35 .8...— BEG 2.96 5.3. .9 8...... 221 scenario also reduces production to such a degree that the steep price declines of the 1980s are not nearly as great, and the marketing order has a correspondingly smaller impact. Prices and returns are also more variable without a marketing order in this scenario, roughly to the same degree as in scenario 81. 6.4. Comparison of Three Marketing Order Simulations A set of performance criteria arising from issues examined in previous chapters serve as a basis for assessing several policy implications of marketing order implementation based on the simulations. The criteria are: (1) grower net revenue, (2) grower price variability, (3) consumer prices, and (4) industry productive capacity (acreage). Another important performance criteria is the change in supply variability from implementing the order, since improving reliability of supply as a means of maintaining sales levels is one of the key reasons for implementing the marketing order. However, this question was not specifically addressed in the simulations, which were focused on price impacts. The models were not designed to assess other impacts relating to the variability of supplies. grower net revenue. A key policy issue is the impact on grower net revenue of marketing order operation. If the orders dampen price declines in large crop years, thus reducing grower losses on downside of supply fluctuations, and if net revenues are positive in other years, the overall result could be above-normal profits to growers for extended periods. This could be considered an undesirable effect of public policy. A study team commissioned to study the impacts of federal marketing orders offered performance guidelines suggesting that marketing orders should neither contribute to above-normal profits by growers nor cause a decline in grower net revenue compared to the situation that 222 would exist without the order.94 Thus an important question to pose is whether marketing order operation contributed to above-normal profits for growers or declines in grower net revenue. In each of the five years in which the tart cherry marketing order was used, net revenue (price minus cost) improved by using the supply management provisions, but did not exceed zero (price was less than average total cost of production per pound in each of the five years). Considering the entire period of analysis in the simulation (1972—1989), tart cherry net revenue averaged just seven tenths of a cent higher using various marketing order supply management provisions than would have been the case with no marketing order. Raisin grower net revenue in the FN study averaged zero under the reserve pool program."s Both of these results suggest that growers did not make above-normal profits as a result of the order. Almond grower net revenue was not computed because of a lack of adequate cost-of-production time series data with which to make comparisons of cost and price. It is also clear that average grower net revenue was not reduced because of the raisin 0r tart cherry marketing orders. The FN analysis showed that mean returns were higher under the marketing order except for the simulations involving a 40% reduction in supply 1’ eSponse. Since tart cherry net revenue was slightly higher on average with supply management than without, grower net revenue was obviously not reduced because of the marketing order. \ 1' "Leo C. Polopolus, Hoy F. Carman, Edward V. Jesse and James D. Shaffer, ”Criteria or Evaluating Federal Marketing Orders: Fruits, Vegetables, Nuts, and Specialty Crops," Washington, DC. National Technical Information Service, Identification Section, 1986. stN offer two caveats to their conclusion, ”...the representative cost series, while 1eating changes in costs over time, may not fully reflect industry-wide averages...net urns varied considerably over time, and were afiected by many factors besides the volume Icon“! tl‘ol program." French and Nuckton, e r'c al sis ind l‘et 223 MW. Part of the coordination problems in these three subsectors stems from the year-to-year price variability from the combination of supply fluctuations and inelastic demand. A key aspect of maintaining demand is providing reliable supplies and steady raw product prices so that manufacturers are encouraged to create new products or at least not to cease production of food products from a particular commodity due to problems of unreliability. Thus marketing order impact on grower price variability is an important criterion. The tart cherry simulation demonstrated that in each of the years of tart cherry marketing order implementation, price declines due to large crops were dampened. Considering the entire period, the standard deviation of tart cherry prices were also slightly smaller with the use of supply management provisions than without. Almond price variability with the marketing order was slightly higher than the no-reserve simulation when measured by standard deviation, but was the same when measured by the coefficient of variation. Thus the almond marketing order apparently did not reduce overall price variability, but it did dampen price declines in large crop years. FN found that raisin prices were less variable with the marketing order than with any of the no-control scenarios. These results suggest that marketing orders as implemented for these commodities have Contributed somewhat to price stability, but that a degree of price and revenue instability I'emained even with use of the marketing orders. @nsgmer prices. The FN analysis suggests that use of the marketing order did not resI-llt in higher average raisin prices to U.S. consumers since the mean of simulated f.o.b. pacl(er prices for all no-control scenarios was about the same or above the historical mean. In contrast, the simulations indicated that f.o.b. prices for almonds and frozen tart cherries were increased by the marketing order. However, the raw product price changes attributable to supply management under federal marketing orders were generally not of a Inaguitude that would bring about significant price increases of consumer products on retail 224 market shelves. This is in part due to the common retailer practice of pricing on the nines and other related SOPs that contribute to the lack of price responsiveness at the retail level to changes in raw product supply levels. In addition, large proportions of each of these three commodities are sold as industrial ingredients, and price changes of the magnitudes considered in these analyses are unlikely to change the price of other manufactured food products, since commodity ingredient costs generally represent only a relatively small part of total retail product cost. lpdustm productive capacig and surplus production. A key issue here is whether a lower risk economic environment due to the existence of a marketing order combined with higher prices for a commodity that can result from operation of the marketing order induces additional planting that contributes to surpluses of a commodity. Evidence of surpluses could include continual or frequent low-use disposal of a portion of the crop. The report by the aforementioned marketing order study team (Polopolus, Carman, Jesse, and Shaffer) and the French and Nuckton analysis provide a useful guideline in this regard. One of the marketing order study team guidelines is that marketing orders should not contribute to chronic surpluses. F N state correctly that additional production can be considered "surplus" only if it results in returns consistently below competitive levels (e.g., Prices below cost of production) or continually require low-use disposal of part of the crop. 30 What happened with tart cherries, almonds, and raisins? Under the tart cherry order, most reserves were carried over and subsequently r e“Based. Only small quantities were diverted to secondary markets in certain large crop y e"firth-definitely not continual low-use disposal. Although the tart cherry market did e‘xpel‘ience persistent overproduction beginning in the mid-1980s, it is not attributable to the marlCeting order. High prices due to shortages in the late 1970s were the primary reason 1‘ . or lI‘iereased plantings and subsequent higher production levels. 225 Diversions to noncommercial outlets that could be considered low-use disposal was even smaller under the almond order, averaging around 4% of total production in the 19805. A large proportion of the almond reserves from 1980 through 1985 were used for domestic market development purposes (not low-use disposal) and the 1987 and 1988 reserves were carried over. Raisin production was higher on average with the marketing order in the FN analysis than with any no-control scenarios. Raisin grape grower returns were higher with the marketing order compared to most no-control scenarios, but nevertheless averaged near zero. Reserve pool quantities were mostly exported or carried over to be sold later. In large crop years, significant diversions to certain noncommercial outlets did occur which could be considered low-use disposal. However, it was not continual and averaged about 4% of raisin production, and FN argue that these diversions should probably not be considered chronic surpluses. The study team argued that it is reasonable to withhold or divert quantities through a marketing order that would otherwise drive returns further below costs. Using this criterion, FN contend that diversions could be viewed as adjustments to unplanned short-run Ontput variations rather than as wasted resources. The marketing order study team also Pointed out that most diversions have been in years of low or negative return. That is certainly applicable in the case of tart cherrieso-marketing order diversions We:- e undertaken in years of negative returns, and thus the failure to store or divert quantities in each of the five large crop years would have driven returns even further below cos“. The non-harvest diversion option was merely a recognition that a certain proportion of tart cherries are not harvested in large crop years with or without a marketing order. Thus non-harvest diversion should also not be considered a means by which the marketing or der contribute to wasted resources. 226 6.5. Suggestions for Model Improvement There are several aspects of the model which could be improved upon. First, alternative specifications of the acreage supply response equation could do a better job of modeling grower planting and removal decisions. The current equation uses grower price as a proxy for net revenue, because grower cost of production data over a sufficiently long time period was not readily available. Additional research could turn up cost data from the 1960s to compute a complete net revenue time series which could be used in place of prices. The lag structure chosen for tart cherries, the simple average of prices in (t-6) to (t-12), could be replaced with an improved lag structure such as polynomial distributed lag which does not weight distant years the same as recent years. Various lag structures were investigated, but a more exhaustive look at lag structures could yield an improved supply response model. Also, the removal decision was not explicitly considered in the current specification, but could be modeled by lagging net revenue over a period such as (t-2) to (t-S). Second, all prices were entered in the equations as nominal prices, because of considerably better performance than with deflated prices with the equations as currently Specified. The prediction errors of key variables were smaller with nominal prices. Alternative specifications of each equation could be attempted using deflated prices, which WOuld be more consistent with economic theory which states that firm and consumer behaVior is guided by real rather than nominal prices. In addition, it would be preferable to use per capita quantities rather than total quantities in the estimated equations. Total quantities were used because of better model performance in terms of predicted values in the base scenarios, given the current specifications of the equations. Third, simulation of the "no marketing order" scenarios runs afoul of the "Lucas critiQUef' The case can be made that the economic structure of a market is sufficiently d 0 [erent without a marketing order than any coefficients estimated with a marketing order 227 cannot be used to model alternative non-order scenarios. However, this criticism is probably too strong. In their raisin model, French and Nuckton attempt to get around this problem by adjusting the parameters that would be most affected by a shift to a market without a marketing order. The key decisions that would be different in the higher risk economic environment without a marketing order were the grower planting decision and the allocation of grapes between the raisin market and the wine (crush) market. As discussed earlier, they adjusted the parameters on these equations and then projected key variables using nine different scenarios. The tart cherry and almond models represent a reasonable "first cut” at modeling the markets without marketing orders, but future research could consider adjusting the planting response downward as was done with the French and N uckton model, and examining which other economic decisions could be similarly adjusted. Fourth, marketing order reserve pool releases that had to be accounted for in the simulation, could be modeled more effectively. One difficulty in modeling the impact of releases was that spring releases were judged to have less of an impact on prices that an equivalent amount of tonnage released in the fall. This was largely because of more elastic demand in the spring due to differing risk perceptions by those buying and selling cherries. The method for representing CAB decision making regarding reserve storage and release in the simulations was through increasing or reducing tonnage. Therefore the method chOsen to approximate the smaller impact of a spring reserve pool release due to changes in demand elasticities was downward adjustment in the simulation of the actual tonnage. This is an area that should be further investigated in future research to see if there are ways to elelicitly model the shifting demand elasticities. The marketing order simulations in this chapter and the application of several p er”formance criteria have provided a means to assess marketing order performance. The final chapter summarizes the roles of marketing orders and cooperatives in responding to t he challenges posed by supply volatility. CHAPTER 7: SUMMARY AND OVERVIEW The problem addressed in this research was agricultural production instability and mismatches in supply and demand in three perennial crop subsectors. Imbalances in supply and demand are a cause for concern, primarily because resources may be wasted by producing greater quantities of agricultural products than can be sold by growers at remunerative prices, with the result that the raw agricultural commodities are worth less than it costs to produce them. Unmet potential demand is another possible consequence. The analysis was limited to three perennial crops. The crop-specific nature of the assets in perennial crop enterprises gives them a distinct set of problems and circumstances. Three perennial crops (tart cherries, almonds, and raisins) were selected which had similar enough marketing institutions that they could meaningftu be compared, yet different enough that comparison would provide useful insights. The supply instability and coordination problems in each of the three commodity 80bsectors were described and diagnosed. Some aspects of the behavior of firms at various sIlbsector levels were analyzed, focusing on certain standard operating procedures (SOPs) that hinder effective coordination. Several coordination mechanisms, including cooperatives and marketing orders, were analyzed and categorized in regard to their actual or potential role in improving subsector s“Dilly-demand balance. Types of cooperatives and alternative marketing strategies emPloyed by cooperatives were examined. Supply management programs, with emphasis on federal marketing orders, were analyzed in regard to their ability to mitigate the consequences of variable supplies. Econometric models of the tart cherry and almond 228 229 industries were developed to estimate the impact on grower prices of implementing a federal marketing order in each of those two subsectors. This chapter reviews key points, accomplishments, and implications of this research. The evidence presented here suggests that committed marketing cooperatives and federal marketing orders have useful roles to play in contributing to the balance of supply and demand in certain perennial crop subsectors. 7.1. Supply Instability, Uncertainty and Coordination Problems This section highlights research findings related to the nature of the uncertainty facing subsector participants and the supply-demand balancing problems facing subsector participants. The use of graphic tools to illustrate the supply-demand balancing problems is also reviewed. 7.1.1. Nature of the Uncertainty Facing Subsector Participants Perennial-crop subsector participants face considerable uncertainty, some of which is substantially different from the uncertainties faced by annual crop subsectors. Part of the uncertainty relates to the supply variability caused by biological and climatic factors Combined with the inability to vary bearing acreage quickly and economically from year to Year. Additional uncertainty relates to the difficulty facing growers of knowing how other EPOWers’ individual production decisions will affect overall productive capacity of the Perennial crop commodity. Growers may make collective mistakes in planting and removal decisions because it is difficult to predict likely aggregate future supply and demand. While this can be a problem for many commodity subsectors, it commonly has more far-reaching col"sequences for perennial crops. In addition, when a series of low price years sends a Signal to growers of excess productive capacity, perennial crop growers tend to adjust slowly, I at‘gely because they have made significant investments in crop-specific assets (especially 230 orchards and related equipment) whose salvage value is near zero or negative. A common result in certain perennial crop subsectors is years of excess capacity, in some cases alternating with periods of underproduction. Variable weather conditions and alternate bearing tendencies of perennials, along with slow adjustment in bearing acreage, commonly contribute to substantial year-to-year fluctuations in crop sizes. This pattern is especially noteworthy in tart cherries. Although tart cherries are much more likely to have short crops than are almonds or raisins, they occur with all three. 7.1.2. Consequences of Supply Variability in the Three Subsectors An important set of questions addressed in this research related to the nature and extent of the supply variability facing the three subsectors. All three subsectors have had problems due to (1) annual fluctuations in supplies and (2) overcapacity in terms of planted acreage. Instability in quantities and prices of commodities makes planning for processors and manufacturers more difficult and products more expensive, reducing” the demand for commodities. Reliance on individual firm storage in some commodity subsectors has generally proven inadequate to the task of carrying sufficient supplies from large-crop years to short-crop years to mitigate the impacts of short supplies. This is largely because the pattern of short crops is too irregular and the risks of making a mistake can be financially disastrous to a firm trying to stabilize annual supplies. Carrying substantial inventories when the following year brings another large crop can be very costly. Periods of overcapacity in terms of planted acreage is another problem common to the three subsectors. If growers collectively plant excess acreage of a perennial crop, many individual growers may endure extended periods of negative net revenue. Furthermore, the simultaneous occurrence of annual supply fluctuations and periods of overcapacity makes 231 it difficult for commodity industry participants to ascertain what demand expansion and supply management strategies to pursue. 7.13. Analytical Methods Used to Illustrate Supply-Demand Imbalance One contribution of this research was the use of graphic tools to illustrate certain supply-demand balance conditions and related vertical coordination aspects. Comparison of long-run productive capacity with demand trends for tart cherries was done in Chapter 2. Supply-demand trends over a period of several years were examined. Tart cherry industry observers stated that the late 19703 were years of underproduction because bearing acreage was in a low productive capacity phase and prices were consistently and substantially above grower cost of production during this period. These high prices contributed to a period of increased planting and thus the late 19805 were years of excess capacity. This was illustrated by Figure 7 in Chapter 2, which showed prices well above costs for a number of years in the late 1970s and prices below costs for an extended period in the late 1980s. To show the shifting supply-demand balance for almonds, another measure was needed due to the lack of cost data. The method chosen involved constructing time series that smoothed both annual production and sales by computing moving averages. The smoothing of production was accomplished by multiplying a moving average of yields by bearing acres. For the period 1972-1979 shown in Figure 11 in Chapter 2, the bars representing average production are approximately the same height as the line representing average sales. This suggests an approximate match of supply and demand, which is consistent with the fact that no marketing order reserves were established during that time. Almond yields and acreage continued to increase in the 19808, and various factors contributed to a slowdown in sales growth. A key factor was that a strong U.S. dollar slowed export sales, contributing to a period of supply-demand imbalance. This is represented by the graph which shows that beginning around 1980, height of the bars in the graph reptes dispo firms ms to he oip agrj Slag SYS th 511 232 representing production were generally above the line representing sales. The excess was disposed of mainly through secondary market diversion via the federal marketing order to firms experimenting with new almond-based products and to USDA commodity feeding programs. Similar moving average graphs were also constructed for raisins and tart cherries to help highlight when periods of excess capacity existed. This portion of the research, including development of means to present comparisons of production and sales data trends, illustrated production variability and the mismatch of agricultural supply (in terms of productive capacity) with demand. It thus helped to set the stage for the subsequent analysis. 7.2. Problems of Vertical Coordination Between Subsector Stages Another phase of the research was to analyze aspects of the vertical marketing system for commodity-based food products that hinder effective vertical coordination. Chapter 3 presented evidence that certain procurement and merchandising practices of food manufacturers and retail food distributors can limit the capacity of prices to coordinate through the vertical stages of a perennial crop subsector. The series of graphs linking four subsector stages illustrated the fact that changes in raw product supplies and prices under certain circumstances have little impact on price changes at the retail level. SOPs such as product line pricing and pricing on the nines can contribute to a lack of retail price responsiveness to supply changes. Retailers commonly employ SOPs, such as pricing on the nines, that can result in a degree of price rigidity in part because they observe that consumers tend to respond very little to price changes within specific ranges (e.g., nine cents or less per unit), unless the price changes are accompanied by additional promotion and/ or merchandising. This inelastic nature of consumer demand for certain processed food products within certain price ranges thus helps bring about the resulting retailer and Inanl C0“? influ often The] 3881 mp: Stra‘ Eng c001 reta mer met 0f mar Pro aeti Pro Pro. ”1a; 233 manufacturer behavior. The graphs with stepped demand curves were illustrations of consumer non-responsiveness to price changes within certain ranges of prices. Retailer decisions about which food items to put on the shelf can significantly influence the quantities purchased. Retailers are in the business of "selling" shelf space and often have little or no incentive to promote a commodity which happens to be in oversupply. They tend to compare the volume of sales and profitability of a particular food product to a set of alternative products to decide whether to provide shelf space for that product. Retailers are likely to use a similar comparative analysis to decide whether to engage in promotion or merchandising activities on behalf of a particular product. Retailer pricing strategies also tend to be heavily affected by the pricing and promotional strategies employed by other retailers within specific markets areas. Since price changes by themselves may play only a limited role in vertical market coordination, an important means of moving additional quantities of a commodity through retail market channels in response to increased supplies is through various non-price merchandising and promotion methods or a combination of price and non-price retail-level merchandising and promotion. Since retailers do not generally undertake merchandising of specific products on their own without specific incentives from suppliers, food manufacturers try to influence retailers to engage in promotion and merchandising, and to provide more shelf space for specific food products. Manufacturers also take on other activities related to promotion and merchandising such as couponing. A food manufacturer will generally undertake promotional activities for branded processed food products with significant profit potential, but not necessarily for food products based on a particular agricultural commodity. Non-grower-owned food manufacturers have few incentives to undertake such actions for food products made from a particular commodity. 234 Growers have the most to lose from the consequences of instability and overproduction. Growers therefore have a greater incentive than other market participants to collectively undertake supply-demand coordination roles, such as attempting through merchandising and promotion to move additional quantities of food products based on these commodities into distribution channels in response to increased production. Thus, another purpose of the research was the examination of selected institutional means for collective supply-demand balancing, especially cooperatives and marketing orders. The three perennial crop subsectors made use of three options to improve vertical coordination: ( 1) large marketing cooperatives that are strongly committed to the commodity subsector, (2) actions to balance long-run supply and demand, and (3) marketing orders for supply management. Summarized below are research results relating to each of those options. 7.3. The Role of Committed Marketing Cooperatives Although grower-processors and small processing cooperatives may desire well- coordinated subsector balancing of supply and demand, they have little ability as individual firms to play a balancing role due to their small size. However, this research explored how larger marketing cooperatives can take on such supply-demand balancing roles with greater likelihood of having a substantial impact on subsector coordination. The term committed marketing cooperative was used in this research to represent the type of cooperative with a potentially greater contribution to subsector coordination than other types of cooperatives. Committed marketing cooperatives have a large share of the total U.S. production of a commodity and a commitment to using the cooperative’s resources to benefit growers by expanding demand and other actions. Committed integrated marketing cooperatives (CIMCs) market a significant portion of member production through strong national branded consumer products. Blue Diamond 235 and Sun Maid both have large shares of the retail market for their respective commodities, so in their roles as food manufacturers they work through their brand position to influence consumer demand and retailer merchandising. They have the ability to significantly influence the demand side in order to help balance subsector supply and demand. The type of cooperative that was labeled in this research as a committed commodity marketing cooperative (CCMC) lacks a strong national brand franchise, but focuses on selling large volumes of processed products to food manufacturers and the food service industry along with retaining a commitment to being a reliable supplier of the commodity. CCMCs have a goal of influencing demand and prices as well as maintaining strong marketing programs for a particular commodity. CCMC members typically represent a large proportion of the total production volume of a commodity, and the cooperative is usually the largest marketing firm in a commodity subsector, or among the largest. 7.3.1. Demand Expansion Roles of Committed Marketing Cooperatives A major goal of both CIMCs and CCMCs is to maintain and expand demand for their particular commodities, and the research focused on understanding different types of demand expansion strategies. Three main aspects of brand marketing strategies examined in this research were: (1) advertising, promotion, and merchandising, (2) development of new markets (mainly export markets), and (3) market research and product development. The approaches followed by CIMCs for advertising, promotion, and marketing of branded products are similar to those of IOF food manufacturers with strong brands, and often include couponing and stimulating the use of special displays by retail food distributors. Examples of new market development strategies include Blue Diamond’s efforts to open up export markets in a number of foreign countries. Brand strategies have also included product development through introduction of new food products as well different sizes and types of packaging. For examples, Blue Diamond increased over time thei vari COW. pro of 1 lab for p05 sui of an (IV re th. Va is: Dr 236 their line of flavored almonds products. Sun-Maid raisins were offered in an increasingly varied array of package sizes and package types. Tart cherry pie filling manufacturers continued to market their regional brands of pie filling through special promotions and occasional limited advertising. Another somewhat unusual approach to expanding the number of branded retail products was licensing the use of the cooperative brand name, such as Sun Maid’s licensing of baking companies to sell raisin bread and raisin English muffins under the Sun-Maid label. These approaches were all intended to maintain or increase grocery store shelf space for branded products made from the perennial crop commodities, and generally have had positive demand expansion impacts, thus improving the supply-demand balance when the subsectors were facing increased production. Value-added strategies are another important part of demand expansion. The sale of special cuts of almonds by Blue Diamond to ready-to-eat breakfast cereal companies are an example of marketing value-added ingredients to a major food manufacturer customer. The fact that Sun-Maid and Blue Diamond have built up national brand recognition over many decades gives them a distinct advantage in carrying out these. strategies. Retailers are much more likely to carry existing and new products because of brand name recognition. Strong brand marketing is much less predominant in the tart cherry subsector. Most tart cherry processors emphasize sales for industrial ingredients and food service, though there are a few exceptions--several firms market branded pie filling. An element that influences the effectiveness of demand expansion through brand and value-added strategies is the versatility of the agricultural commodity in terms of potential for new product development. This is an important lesson for participants in other commodity industries. Versatility in terms of the number of different processed food products that can be made from an agricultural commodity is in part due to the commodity’s inherent characteristics and in part due to the innovativeness of people working in product develOp exploiti; appeal retail d methoc almow oi difi paste. aPPFC dfi'el POSsi rElia has subj adv the 5U in 237 development. Almond demand expansion by Blue Diamond was facilitated both by exploiting the inherent versatility of almonds and by innovative thinking about ways to appeal to consumer tastes and preferences. Contributing factors to the success in almond retail demand expansion included the creation of numerous new products with alternative methods of salting, roasting, adding flavors, slicing, packaging, and so on. Increased use of almonds as ingredients in manufactured products was achieved through developing a number of different ways of processing, including cutting (slicing, dicing), blanching, and making paste. Demand expansion in other commodity industries depends on taking a broad-based approach to assessing potential food product uses in terms of either branded product development by cooperatives or IOFs, or as a focus for generic demand expansion programs, possibly funded through state or federal marketing orders. One inducement for new product development is guaranteeing a food manufacturer reliable supplies at prices below prevailing market prices for a period of several years. This has been done to some extent by committed marketing cooperatives. This approach is subject to free rider problems since other firms marketing the same commodity can take advantage of futures sales opportunities without incurring the product development costs. Committed marketing cooperatives need to develop strategies that assure their members of the benefits of product development efforts. New product development can also be achieved in conjunction with marketing order supply management. A means to encourage a food manufacturer to develop a new food product is to undertake secondary market diversion for certain quantities of a commodity for several successive years to manufacturers willing to experiment with new product uses, at prices below those prevailing in the primary market. Another research task focused on identifying specific demand expansion responses to overproduction. The almond and raisin industries both provided useful examples. One example of a demand expansion strategy was Blue Diamond’s response to rapidly growing 238 production in the 19805. The cooperative launched a major advertising campaign featuring scenes of growers chest-high in almonds in an attempt to communicate overproduction problems to consumers. Evidence based on interviews of almond industry representatives suggested that this approach helped increase almond sales in response to the overproduction problem. An important raisin industry response to large supplies in the 19805 was to substantially increase generic promotion through the celebrated "dancing raisins" advertising program. This innovative advertising program was carried out by the raisin industry’s generic promotion board. The raisin cooperative strongly supported this initiative and tailored some of its brand promotions to tie into the dancing raisin theme. The results of interviews with raisin industry participants suggested that the dancing raisins campaign, in conjunction with other initiatives, helped to reduce the oversupply problem by effectively expanding demand for raisins. In summary, cooperatives and generic demand expansion organizations have played key roles in balancing supply and demand in their respective subsectors by undertaking these activities in response to annual supply fluctuations and long-term production trends. For raisins and almonds, the ability to sell a large proportion of total production as branded retail products has enabled almond and raisin growers to react collectively to changing supply conditions by initiating various additional measures to increase sales. Committed marketing cooperatives have led the way in demand expansion for raisins and almonds through their efforts to apply the several types of brand and value-added strategies. This represents a key supply-demand coordination function for cooperatives that have a large share of the consumer market through a strong national brand position and a large proportion of total U.S. tonnage of that subsector. 239 7.3.2. Changing Roles of Committed Marketing Cooperatives A key implication of this research is that certain types of cooperatives have a role in promoting a better match of supply and demand in specific commodity subsectors. However, the ability to perform this role has declined for some cooperatives. For example, some evidence of Blue Diamond’s declining role comes from its decision to refocus its strategies because of a declining share of almond production. The cooperative made a policy decision to close membership and focus on effective marketing of a smaller proportion of the total U.S. almond tonnage than the cooperative has had in the recent past. This points out a general problem that can occur with demand expansion efforts by committed marketing cooperatives. The cooperative incurs the expenditure of developing new products and expanding export opportunities. Other firms can frequently take advantage of the increased sales opportunities created by the cooperatives. Growers supplying those firms expand production, eroding the cooperative’s share of total production. Free riding by non-member growers and IOF handlers can act as a disincentive for cooperative demand expansion efforts, hindering the ability of committed marketing to play supply-demand balancing roles. Opportunities for cooperatives to develop new commodity-based retail products in the future are probably limited for cooperatives that are not currently marketing a portion of their members’ production through branded retail products. The main reasons are the substantial financial barriers to entry into national markets for branded grocery products. New product develOpment is expensive and risky. There are very large financial requirements for undertaking advertising programs to achieve successful product differentiation and to establish new products in the market. Cooperatives acting in their role as food manufacturing firms must engage in large-scale advertising and promotional activities to influence retailer merchandising and the selection of products carried on supermarket shelves. Additional requirements for retail demand expansion for branded 240 retail products are substantial sales forces and/or networks of brokers and distributors for distribution of the food products. Substantial promotional resources are also required to maintain and increase food service sales such as influencing the selection of food products on the menus of a national fast food chains. Despite the positive role for cooperative brand marketing up to the present in balancing supply and demand, such a supply-demand coordination role for cooperatives may be more limited in the future because of the financial barriers to entry. 7.33. Future Research on the Role of Committed Marketing Cooperatives An important accomplishment of this research was categorizing and classifying types of coordination mechanisms, cooperatives, and marketing strategies. However, the research did not entail gathering specific figures on the quantities going into various categories. Nor was there an attempt to quantify the extent to which cooperatives or generic demand expansion commissions have increased sales successfully in the face of supply increases. This research focused on making observations and discerning key trends, based on the interviews conducted and publications reviewed. Future research can attempt to quantitatively assess the success (or lack of it) of cooperative and generic demand expansion efforts. The analysis for this research did not specifically define the threshold level for a cooperative to be categorized as a committed marketing cooperatives. Refining the concept to specify more precisely what is a sufficiently large proportion of total production to be a CIMC or a CCMC is another area for future research. 7.4. Long-Run Supply-Demand Balancing The long run supply-demand balancing approaches that were investigated included approaches to reduce acreage when overplanting had occurred and to avoid overplanting. 241 Raisin acreage reduction has been accomplished to some degree through the Raisin Diversion Program (RDP) as part of the raisin marketing order. Some growers that participated in the RDP removed their vines entirely, thus reducing industry productive capacity. However, most participants in the RDP only trimmed their vines to eliminate production for a single year. An orchard removal incentive program for tart cherries was proposed but never implemented. The tart cherry orchard removal program was intended to reduce acreage to a level at which quantities produced would be closer to quantities typically sold in commercial markets at prices approximating average grower cost of production, thus contributing to an improved balance of supply and demand. Methods of avoiding overplanting examined in this research were: (1) dissemination on information on production projections and related long-run market analysis, (2) limiting cooperative membership, (3) stock tonnage contracts, and (4) acreage contracts. At different periods in the past, Blue Diamond attempted to influence planting levels by disseminating market analyses and projections of future levels of excess almond supply and by limiting cooperative membership. Industry participants indicated in interviews that neither method was effective in bringing long-run supply and demand into balance, and the efforts were subsequently abandoned. When Blue Diamond attempted through information dissemination to influence production capacity (bearing acreage), cooperative officials found that the information was widely ignored by growers. In addition, almond sales increased by greater proportions than expected, which ironically benefitted most those growers who increased their plantings, in contradiction of the cooperative’s suggested reductions based on the long-run market outlook. When Blue Diamond limited membership, non-member production continued to increase steadily, eroding the c00perative share. Limiting cooperative membership is only likely to be effective if a cooperative sells most of its output under strong brands and if the 242 cooperative’s share of total U.S. production of the particular commodity is quite high, perhaps 70-80% or more of total production. Examples of such cooperatives include Welch’s for Concord grape products and Ocean Spray for cranberries. Blue Diamond cooperative membership has accounted for around 50% of production in recent years, and cooperative officials expect that figure to decline as non-member production expands and is marketed through IOFs. Stock tonnage has been used in the tart cherry subsector to coordinate supplies with expected sales for one of the larger tart cherry cooperatives. This approach is most appropriate for cooperatives which market most of their product through strong national brands. The reason for this is that strong brands provide a market segment somewhat separate from the unbranded commodity portion of the market. The demand for branded commodity-based food products in more inelastic than the product sold in the undifferentiated commodity markets. Since supply requirements for a particular brand are more predictable than for a commodity as a whole, brand marketers may be able to use stock tonnage to avoid oversupplying the market for their brand. The supply-demand balancing impact for the subsector may be substantial if cooperatives that use stock tonnage market a large portion of total crop production. Neither of these aspects has been characteristic of the tart cherry industry, and the long-run supply-demand coordination impact of the stock tonnage approach has been correspondingly limited. Acreage contracts are common in the almond subsector. However, acreage contracts have not been used for long-run supply-demand balancing in the almond, raisin, or tart cherry subsectors. Although several of these long-run supply-influencing approaches have been tried in the three subsectors that were studied, it is difficult to quantify whether any of them influenced planting decisions on a large enough scale to have a significant impact on bringing productive capacity into better balance with demand trends. Presentation of these ap] of 1 m2 ha to by fre lar m: no ad of fer of flu Sta me Dr 243 approaches nevertheless provides a starting point for considering how various combinations of long-run supply-demand balancing measures might be employed in a particular subsector. 7.5. The Role of Supply Management Implementation of marketing strategies and demand expansion efforts by committed marketing cooperatives and through generic demand expansion programs is enhanced by having reliable supplies of a commodity at prices that do not fluctuate sharply from one year to the next. Firms at various subsector stages, including cooperatives, are negatively affected by the reduced supplies and high prices in short crop years. Committed marketing cooperatives in all three subsectors are subject to significant free-rider problems in dealing with some of the supply problems. When cooperatives carry large inventories as a result of large crops, or attempt to divert excess supplies to secondary markets, their members bear the burden of short-run coordination, and non-members do not. Supply management programs through federal marketing orders have helped to address this free-rider problem of dealing with surplus supplies in large crop years and lack of supplies in short crop years. 7.5.1. Supply Management Provisions of Federal Marketing Orders Chapter 5 presented the three main types of supply management provisions of federal marketing orders which are commonly implemented to mitigate the consequences of annual supply fluctuations. Reserve pools address the problem of annual supply fluctuation through storing a portion of grower deliveries in large-crop years and releasing some or all of the storage reserve in short-crop years. Market allocation provides another stabilization approach by removing excess product in large crop years from the designated major markets. This is more appropriately used in situations of persistent oversupply. Diversion to secondary markets (market allocation) is the means to remove product from fr. 0f Wa Yea T812 hig} Wet. 311m 244 the primary market, and some secondary market uses involve experimenting with new product development. The third set of provisions, non-production or non-harvest diversion, provides additional flexibility in managing excess supplies. Certain supply management programs through federal marketing orders have contributed to supply and price stability and have addressed problems related to short-run aspects of supply-demand balancing. A major contribution has been to alleviate some of the negative consequences of supply instability by helping to promote increased sales and to prevent erosion of demand through more stable commodity supplies. The supply management provisions of the federal marketing orders have also helped dampen price declines in large crop years, thus mitigating the negative impact on growers. 7.5.2. Modeling Federal Marketing Order Price Impacts The question of the impact of supply management programs analyzed in this study focused on the grower price impact of federal marketing order implementation. Chapter 2 pointed out that large tart cherry crops commonly result in grower prices falling below typical grower total cost of production and sometimes below variable cost of production. The decline in prices is dampened by removing a portion of the temporary surplus supplies from the market through secondary market diversion or reserve pool storage. This aspect of the research was designed to estimate the magnitude of the price change. The question was: How much lower would grower prices have gone without the marketing order in those years in which the marketing order supply management provisions were implemented? A related question was: In certain years when the marketing order was not used, how much higher would grower prices have been if a marketing order had been used? The answers were sought through development and use of econometric models of the tart cherry and almond markets. Comparisons with an econometric study of the raisin market by French and draw varit have Oldl aPP of n esta Sim 198 of; Wet gro 00n of ; esri Re File Sm: gm DE:- prlc 245 and Nuckton were also made. The French and Nuckton study provided guidance in developing the tart cherry and almond models. The estimated price impacts of the tart cherry marketing orders from the model varied by subsector stage. The tart cherry simulation indicated that grower prices would have been lower without the marketing order in each of the five years that the marketing order was used. The price impact on the grower level of marketing order implementation appeared to be substantial in some years and moderate in other years. The last two years of marketing order use, 1984 and 1985, in which reserve percentages of 15% and 7% were established, were good examples of the impact the simulation was intended to measure. The simulation results indicated that grower price would have been 5c and 1c lower in 1984 and 1985, respectively, if the marketing order had not been used. This represented price changes of 20% and 7%, respectively, relative to the actual grower price. For tart cherry processed prices in 1984 and 1985, the f.o.b. frozen price impacts were 8c and 3c per pound, respectively. Although the tart cherry model estimated only grower and processor prices, price impacts at the retailer and manufacturer levels were also considered. The analysis in Chapter 3 of retailer and manufacturer SOPs, and the rigidity of retail-level pricing within certain price ranges, indicated that the f.o.b. price changes estimated in the simulation would likely have had little impact on consumer product pricing. Retail level price increases would have been unlikely not only because of product line pricing and pricing on the nines, but also because the tart cherry ingredients represent a small part of the total cost of the processed food product. For almonds, evidence from the econometric simulation indicated that substantial grower price impacts from marketing order use occurred in 1987 and 1988. Grower prices were an estimated 33¢ and 27¢ per pound higher due to the marketing order. Reserve percentages in those two years were 18% and 25 %, respectively. The higher f.o.b. almond prices due to the use of the almond marketing order reserve in the late 19805 may have nu UH Us ye: the the rer Ina con imr mar rev, fro; ave] relat Orde] 246 been enough to bring about price changes of almond-based food products of a food manufacturer. However, the estimated price changes resulting from marketing order supply management represent dampening of the price declines that would have resulted from large crops in the absence of the marketing order. F.o.b. almond prices averaged around $1.00 per pound during the late 19805 when the marketing order was used for supply management. Use of the marketing order mainly prevented the f.o.b. price from declining in large-cop years substantially below $1.00 per pound, which was the average price level prevailing at that time. On the issue of retail prices, a useful area for additional research would be to extend the simulation analyses for almonds and tart cherries to further assess the price impact of removing various quantities from the primary market through marketing order supply management. The impact of the marketing order on grower net revenue was another aspect considered. The analysis showed that in each year of tart cherry marketing order implementation, net grower revenue was higher than it would have been without the marketing order, but that based on average prices and costs, growers still had negative net revenue. Similarly, the French and Nuckton study indicated that mean net grower returns from raisin production were higher as a result of the marketing order, but nevertheless averaged around zero for the period under study (1964-1985). There is room for simulation model improvement regarding the estimated price impacts for tart cherries and almonds. Since the baseline historical simulations indicated relatively large errors in predicting grower and f.o.b. prices, the estimated price impacts of supply management should be viewed with caution. Alternative specification of key behavioral relationships may reduce the margin of error in estimating price impacts. The stabilizing effect on supplies over several years is another feature of marketing order supply management. Table 13 in Chapter 5 showed the net stabilizing effect of the tart Che SIC Cf CC 247 cherry marketing order by storing reserve cherries in 1972, 1975, and 1980, and releasing stored cherries the following year, which in each case was a short-crop year. The reduction in supply fluctuations attributable to the order over each two-year period ranged from 5 to 32 million pounds. Reducing the impact of shortages in short crop years helps prevent erosion of demand caused by unavailability of the raw product. This aspect of the analysis could be extended in future research by attempting to assess what additional sales took place because of the additional supply made available through the tart cherry reserve pool. 7.5.3. Differences in Use of Supply Management Among the Three Subsectors Supply conditions have differed among the three commodity subsectors. The greater number of short crops of tart cherries when compared with almond and raisin production patterns was an important measure of variability; between 1967 and 1991, there were ten short tart cherry crops, compared to three for almonds and four for raisins. The larger number of short crops in years following large crops was a key reason for making greater use of the storage reserve pool in the marketing order for tart cherries than was done for almonds or raisins. The three commodity industries have emphasized different supply management approaches depending on their differing supply conditions. Reserve pools have stabilized supplies through storage of a portion of grower deliveries in large crop years and release of the reserves either later in the same season or in subsequent short crop years. The tart cherry industry has tended to make greater use of reserve pool storage due to its greater frequency of short crops. This was intended to contribute to maintaining demand through more reliable supplies. Because almonds and raisins tend to have frequent large crops but few short crops, use of marketing order provisions has emphasized market allocation which diverts portions of the crops to secondary markets. The main secondary market outlet for both almonds and 248 raisins for two decades was the export market. This contributed to the growth of expor. markets to the point where export sales were no longer residual outlets, but had become primary commercial market channels. In the 19705 and 19803, market allocation provisions of the marketing orders emphasized using lower-priced raisins and almonds for new product development and diversion to such uses as USDA feeding programs. The tart cherry industry is especially interesting in terms of the large number of programs that have been considered by the industry for dealing with supply volatility and periods of overcapacity of cherry orchards. A number of different programs were considered before the federal marketing order was implemented in 1972. After the termination of the order in 1986, tart cherry industry participants discussed and analyzed a wide variety of supply management options, including creation of different kinds of special cooperatives to facilitate group action in reducing acreage and/or for dealing with annual supply volatility. None of these programs have yet been implemented. The industry has recently developed a new marketing order program proposal. Under the previous tart cherry federal marketing order (1972-1986), supply management provisions were implemented five times. During that time, the relative emphasis of the different provisions varied. Reserve pool storage was the provision most emphasized. Secondary market diversion would have been more emphasized during the 19805 had the order continued because short crops were becoming less frequent due to the increase in acreage leading to a situation of persistent overproduction. Non-harvest diversion was the option chosen by a number of growers in 1972, but use of that option declined to near zero in subsequent years when the previous marketing order was implemented. An additional area for future research would be to examine the differing impacts of using different marketing order supply management provisions. For example, simulation analysis could be undertaken to see by how much price impacts would vary if in certain years market allocation was used instead of reserve pool storage or vice versa. Such 249 analyses could provide decision-making guidelines for people serving on marketing order administrative bodies that are charged with making supply management decisions. 7.5.4. Supply Management: Applications to Other Commodity Industries An important question is how might a perennial crop commodity industry choose among the supply management coordination mechanisms examined herein to address specific problems. An objective of this research was to highlight some of the conditions under which specific coordination mechanisms could be most appropriately applied. The supply management-oriented coordination mechanisms investigated were: 1) reserve pool storage, 2) market allocation, 3) non-harvest/non-production diversion, and 4) acreage removal. An approach for deciding upon the appropriate supply management tools for specific commodity industries can logically include examination of the circumstances and problems facing that industry, followed by assessment of which mechanisms might be used to address those problems. Characteristics of the specific commodity are important: 1) crop production variability patterns and causes, 2) feasibility of methods for temporary non- production diversion, 3) storage capability and cost, 1. MW. If the dominant production variation pattern is chiefly one of frequent short crops in years following large crops, then reserve pool storage is likely to be the more appropriate tool of the four listed above. This pattern was characteristic of the tart cherry subsector in the 19703 and early 19805. Release of stored commodities from reserve pools in short crop years contributed to market stability. On the other hand, market allocation is especially relevant for a subsector which has an historic supply pattern of several excessive supply years in succession and for which short crops are not frequent. The third provision, non-harvest diversion, chiefly serves as an additional means to give growers credit for diversion when the limited number of secondary markets opt crop years, The When peter from a red Re Vag‘m g w 0f perenn The exarr Therefor Shift hep ‘0 annu; Supply r 2. E Orcharc‘ mnsid. di"'ersi manag this m it the simm he“ . “he, b10C): 250 markets options are overwhelmed by the extent of the temporary surplus in certain large- crop years, leaving certain growers without alternative diversion outlets. The fourth provision, acreage removal (or orchard/vine removal) is appropriate when perennial crops are in a period of excessive capacity and the industry could benefit from a reduction in the total number of acres planted to a specific crop. Recognizing that various factors can contribute to supply variability is also important. Varying weather conditions is a major factor in the substantial production shifts of a number of perennial crops. However, changes in market utilization of a crop can also be a factor. The example cited in this research was that raisin-type grapes have uses in multiple markets. Therefore, a factor that contributed to raisin production variability was grower decisions to shift between the crush market and the raisin market. With additional factors contributing to annual variability, there is a need for greater flexibility and innovativeness in developing supply management tools. ethods for tem ora n- odu '0 've io . Ifit is feasible to make orchard or vines cease production for a single year, this affords a commodity industry considerable flexibility in dealing with temporary excess production. Non-production diversion can be used in conjunction with the other federal marketing order supply management tools to reduce supplies in particular large-crop years. The only crop for which this method is currently practiced is raisins. The Raisin Diversion Program is made possible by the fact that preventing grape production on particular vines for a single year is a fairly simple procedure of cutting off the ”spurs” that produce grapes. Spurs grow back again the next year so that production resumes. The same effect may be feasible in the future for other crops by aborting blooms by spraying (or possibly by some other method) so that the blooms will produce no fruit in a given year. If it can be made technically and economically feasible, this can be an additional supply management tool for other perennial crops. 3.;fl thecr there forrz flora; rahhr butn feser EVE“ three deg“ indu: they 8T0“ owe a 00 geog acrio Chan 8T0“; reprfi 251 3. Storage capability and cost. For any of the storage supply management tools to work, the commodity must be storable. The cheaper it is store the commodity, the more flexibility there is. Tart cherries are stored frozen, which is a more expensive than storage methods for raisins or almonds. This adds to the risk to an individual firm of making mistaken storage decisions. Almonds can be stored in large bins or piles inside warehouses, and raisins can be stored outside in large boxes covered with tarpaulins with periodic fumigation but no refrigeration. Thus, a commodity industry must consider the cost and ease of storage. However, the cost of storage is only one among many factors to consider, and reserve pool storage may be an appropriate method for short-run supply demand balancing even when storage costs are high. Even though tart cherries are the most expensive of the three commodities to store, reserve pool storage was appropriately emphasized to a greater degree by the tart cherry industry. 7.6. Implications for Marketing Order Establishment for Other Commodities Key elements that facilitate establishment of a marketing order by commodity industry are 1) a widespread sentiment shared by growers of a particular commodity that they face a serious supply-demand balancing problem, 2) substantial agreement among growers that the problems can be significantly reduced through establishment of a marketing order, and 3) a consensus that a marketing order is clearly the best alternative. Establishing a consensus on subsector problems and a sense of community can be facilitated by the geographic proximity of growers. A sense of community can be channeled into collective action when the growers of a particular commodity face an identifiable set of problems and challenges that can be addressed by the actions of an organized group representing those growers. This research has examined examples in three subsectors how this sense of community among growers is sometimes expressed through membership in cooperatives that represent a significant proportion of all growers in a region or the nation (and also I- 252 representing a large proportion of total production), and through the establishment of a marketing order. Committed marketing cooperatives are in some instances influential in the creation and maintenance of marketing orders. A recommendation for future marketing order development is that new national enabling legislation should contain no commodity-specific or geographic restrictions on the creation of marketing orders. Commodity-specific restrictions are not needed. Any group of agricultural producers should have the right to organize and establish a federal marketing order for a particular commodity if growers decide among themselves that there is sufficient economic justification, sense of collective self-interest, and capacity to organize. The analysis of the three subsectors tends to support this policy recommendation by showing that the use of supply management tools has had beneficial impacts for supply-demand balancing. Shaffer concurs that there is no need to limit the scope of orders, since ”the problems of organizing a community of interest to support these types of orders is limiting enough.“ Establishing a marketing order can be facilitated by a geographic concentration of growers, but no geographic restrictions on the right to establish a marketing order are needed. The physical proximity of growers makes a sense of collective identity among growers of a specific commodity more likely to develop and continue. Establishment and continuation of the raisin and almond marketing orders was aided by the fact that all raisin and almond growers are within fairly close proximity to each other in California. Establishment of the tart cherry marketing order was helped by the fact that over two thirds of tart cherry production was within the state of Michigan. However, subsequent organizing problems since the demise of the tart cherry marketing order in 1986 are in part attributable ”James D. Shaffer, ”Designing Marketing Order Programs for the Future,” Presentation at the Conference of the Food and Agricultural Marketing Consortium, Alexandria, VA, January 13-14, 1994, Staff Paper No. 94-7, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, February, 1994. 253 to the difficulties of organizing farmers across several states, extending from New York to Oregon. Marketing orders could be effective and flexible tools for supply-demand coordination if new national enabling legislation authorized the creation of federal marketing orders with each of the provisions examined in this research. Individual marketing orders could include some or all of the four types of supply management provisions examined in this research: 1) reserve pool storage, 2) market allocation, 3) non- harvest/non-production diversion, and 4) acreage removal. It would be up to the industry marketing order development committee and the supervisory body of each marketing order to draw up guidelines for determining under what conditions specific provisions should be invoked. Representatives of the commodity industry sitting on the administrative committee would assess supply-demand balance conditions and decide which provisions are most appropriate at a given point in time. The marketing order language should allow the administrative committees considerable flexibility to make decisions. As is the case now, periodic grower renewal referenda should be required to ensure that growers continue to support the order. Where there is substantial agreement among growers on the performance of a particular marketing order, grower referenda would likely approve continuance by substantial margins, as has been the case with almonds and raisins. 7.7. The Role of Commodity Promotion and Research Programs The national marketing order enabling legislation discussed in the previous section should also contain provisions, similar to provisions in the current legislation, for the establishment of commodity promotion and research programs as a part of federal marketing orders. Effective commodity promotion can adjust demand to more nearly match supply at prices consistent with costs. However, the question of when to engage in promotional activities for commodity-based products is an important issue. This research 254 indicates that subsector supply-demand balancing can be improved when promotional programs are designed to undertake actions consistent with supply conditions, yet are flexible and have a multi-year horizon. Promotion is especially appropriate during periods with excessive supplies. During periods of short supply, promotional programs should be reduced somewhat in scope, but there must be some continuity in promotional activities for a program to remain effective. Commodity research for new product development is an additional aspect of generic commodity demand expansion strategy. A useful goal for commodity research organizations would be to allocate funds for research that focuses on identifying commodity attributes desired by consumers and by firms that handle the product in various stages of the marketing chain. Shaffer points out that research on food product attributes desired by consumers can guide related research focusing on developing economical methods to produce such attributes.” Efforts should be made where possible to complement new product development efforts of committed marketing cooperatives, where they exist, and new product opportunities made possible through marketing order secondary market diversion to firms willing to experiment with new product development if they can obtain lower-cost reliable supplies of the commodity. 7.8. Additional Policy Implications Since committed marketing cooperatives and federal marketing orders serve useful functions in balancing supply and demand in some perennial crop commodity subsectors, the U.S. government should continue to promote cooperatives and facilitate the development and use of federal marketing orders for supply management. In the 19705 and 19805 the federal government took policy positions hostile to cooperatives with large market shares 9“'J. D. Shaffer, "Designing Marketing Order Programs for the Future. 255 of certain commodities, and to the use of supply management provisions of federal marketing orders for fruits, vegetables and specialty crops. The government expressed considerable concern over the possible anti-competitive effects of large cooperatives and the combination of large cooperatives and supply management-oriented federal marketing orders. The results of this research suggest that cooperatives and marketing orders operating in conjunction with each other can under certain circumstances serve useful and legitimate economic purposes in perennial crop subsectors. However, the issue of possible undue price enhancement through supply management should not be ignored. The federal marketing order guidelines proposed by the Marketing Order Study Team discussed in Chapter 6 indicated that marketing order supply management programs should not contribute to above-normal grower profits. The evidence from the marketing orders simulation analyses suggests that growers did not make above-normal profits. Design of future marketing orders should consider whether there are sufficient safeguards against undue price enhancement. This is another policy area that merits additional research. A key point in this regard is that the committed marketing cooperatives and federal marketing orders working in combination have been able to influence demand and supply to a certain extent in their efforts to bring about a better balance, but have not attempted to control agricultural production. The ever-present likelihood of increased agricultural production in response to profitable agricultural prices from supply management puts a limit on potential anti-competitive effects of supply management. Low barriers to entry are typical of many, types of crop production, including most perennial crops. If supply management is used to maintain grower prices at levels well above grower cost of production, increased plantings from existing growers and new growers are likely and could bring about a situation of excess productive capacity. The additional acreage would (\S 256 undercut the supply-demand balancing role that the supply management program was intended to ameliorate. Large market shares held by cooperatives with strong national brands have not led to anti-competitive pricing effects in the tart cherry, almond and raisin subsectors. On the contrary, they have led to improved vertical market coordination. Having the ability to influence retailer merchandising practices in their role as food manufacturers has provided an important subsector coordination function for cooperatives in their efforts to coordinate fluctuating supplies with demand. Some future demand-related efforts to improve subsector coordination for commodities lacking products with national brand franchises will likely come from grower collective action through generic commodity promotion organizations. Because of the advantages of demand expansion as one tool for supply-demand balancing, national government policy should be to encourage such programs. Efforts of commodity industry participants—growers and firms in downstream stages of the subsectors--should be focused on assessing consumer preferences and developing commodity-based food products that match those preferences, and on influencing merchandising variables to ensure that consumers are informed about new and existing products. Growers can achieve this through collective action in the form of committed marketing cooperatives. Retail branded product marketing is a significant component of demand expansion that contributes to balancing supply and demand for perennial crops. The value-added industrial market for commodity ingredients and for food service will continue to play important roles, as will the undifferentiated commodity markets. Supply management should continue to play a complementary role to the demand-related efforts in subsector supply-demand balancing. 257 7.9. Concluding Comment The value of this kind of research lies in the comprehensiveness of the examination of supply-demand balancing and vertical coordination roles. A thorough examination of the nature of the production instability facing particular crop subsectors helps to distinguish in what respects the causes and consequences are similar or different. In the tart cherry, almond, and raisin subsectors, some similarities in supply fluctuation patterns led to the adoption of similar approaches to mitigating the consequences. However, differences in the supply patterns led to emphasizing to different degrees the use of specific provisions of federal marketing orders. Understanding the similarities and differences provides some insights into the potential application of these approaches in other subsectors. Using the subsector framework as an analytical tool provides a means to examine the interactions between vertical stages of a subsector. The incentives facing firms at a particular subsector level can be examined to analyze how the adoption of SOPs such as product line pricing affects vertical coordination. Because price changes by themselves may play only a limited role in vertical market coordination, this research examined various means by which subsector supply-demand balancing can be improved through combinations of price and non-price merchandising and promotion approaches. A number of examples were presented to show how committed marketing cooperatives take on such supply-demand balancing roles. The cooperative role in demand expansion can be better understood by examining various aspects, including brand strategies and the marketing of value-added ingredients to food manufacturers, as well as supplying the food service industry. Understanding the interaction of various marketing-related institutions contributes to our knowledge of how commodity marketing systems can be improved. Supply management is likely to continue to play a complementary role to the demand-related efforts in subsector supply-demand balancing. Comprehensive comparative analysis contributes to our understanding of the dynamic, evolving nature of perennial crop subsectors. '8 Bl 258 BIBLIOGRAPHY Almond Board of California, "Almond Statistics,” various years. ”Background Economic Analysis and 1986 Marketing Policy of Cherry Administrative Board,” May 1986. Blue Diamond Growers, Inc., Almond Facts Nov/Dec 1984. Blue Diamond Growers, Inc., Almond facts, May/June 1985. Blue Diamond Growers, Inc., Almond Facts July 1986. Blue Diamond Growers, Inc., Almond Facts Sep/ Oct 1987. Blue Diamond Growers, Inc., Almond Eacts, May/June 1991. Blue Diamond Growers, Inc., ”Annual Report 1987-1988." Blue Diamond Growers, Inc., ”Annual Report 1988-89." California Almond Growers Exchange, Inc., "Annual Report 1979-80." California Almond Grower’s Exchange, ”Annual Report 1981-82.” California Almond Growers Exchange, "Annual Report 1983-84." California Almond Growers Exchange, Statement by CAGE presented to the Study Team on Performance Criteria for Federal Marketing Orders, 1986. Cherry Marketing Institute, ”Report on Michigan Tart Cherry Survey,” Okemos, Michigan, 18 January 1991. Dalziell, Ian, ”Sources of Agricultural Marketing Instability,” Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State University, 1985. Forker, Olan D. and Ronald W. Ward, 0 i e Mgaspm emgpt pf Generic floggams, New York: Lexington Books, 1993. French, Ben C. and Carole Franke Nuckton, "An Empirical Analysis of Economic Performance Under the Marketing Order for Raisins, MW Agricultural Emnomics (73: 3), August 1991. 259 French, Ben C. and Lois Schertz Willett, "An Econometric Model of the U.S. Asparagus Industry," Giannini Res. Rpt. No. 340, University of California, September 1989. Hamm, Larry G., ”Food Distributor Procurement Practices: Their Implications for Food System Structure and Coordination," Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, 1981. Hinman, Donald L. and Donald J. Ricks, ”Supply Management Alternatives for the Tart Cherry Industry,” Journal of Food Distribution Research, v. 23, no.1 (February 1992). Hirschman, A.O., Exit, Voice and Loyalg, Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970. Kinnucan, H.W. and others, "Research and Marketing Issues Facing Commodity Promotion Programs," in D.I. Padberg, ed.,Food and Aggicultural Magketing issues for the 215t Centug, FAMC 93-1, Food and Agricultural Marketing Consortium, Texas A&M Univ., 1993. Knutson, Ronald A., "The Impact of Cooperatives on Market Performance, Subsector Coordination, and the Organization of Agriculture,” in Aggiculturai Cooperatives and the Public Interest: Proceedings of a North Central Regional Research Committee Sponsored Wogigshop, St. Lpuis, MO, Jpn; 6-8 1977 NC. Project 117 Monograph 4, Research Division, College of Agricultural and Life Sciences, University of Wisconsin, Madison, September 1978. Marion, Bruce, The Ozgapizatiop and Egfiogpance of the U.S. Eppd Sfitgm, Lexington: D.C. Heath and Company, 1986. Mighell, Ronald and Lawrence Jones, Ve ' o d' at' ' . icut USDA, Economic Research Service, Farm Economics Division, Agricultural Economics Report No. 19, February 1963. Nuckton, C.F., B.C. French, and G.C. King, Ah flopometgic Analysis of the Califomia Raisin Industiy, Gianninni Foundation Research Report No. 339, University of California, December 1988. Peterson, Christopher J. Cooperative Bg' l_( and Betpm Strategig, Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Cornell University, 1992. Polopolus, Leo C., Hoy F. Carman, Edward V. Jesse and James D. Shaffer, "Criteria for Evaluating Federal Marketing Orders: Fruits, Vegetables, Nuts, and Specialty Crops,” Washington, DC. National Technical Information Service, Identification Section, 1986. Raisin Administrative Committee, "Marketing Policy," Fresno CA, various years. 260 Bed jifeg Cherries: Crop Statistics and Market Analysis, (Michigan Agricultural Cooperative Marketing Association--Red Tart Cherry Growers Marketing Committee; American Agricultural Marketing Association-Cherry Advisory Committee), Lansing, Michigan. Ricks, Donald J. Ricks, L.G. Hamm and WC. Chase-Lansdale, fljhe Iijart Chem Snbsector of U.S. Aggiculture: A Review of Organization and Perfohmance, N.C. Project 117, Monograph 12, Research Division, College of Agriculture and Life Sciences, University of Wisconsin - Madison, July 1987. Ricks, Donald, "Tart Cherry Orchard Buyout Bidding Approaches," Staff Paper 90- 24, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, March 1990. Shaffer, James D., "Thinking About Farmers’ Cooperatives, Contracts, and Economic Coordination,” in Coo erat've eo : New A roaches ed Jeffrey S. Royer, Washington DC: USDA, ACS Service Report 18, July 1987, 61-62. Shaffer, James D. "Designing Marketing Order Programs for the Future,” (paper forthcoming in 1994). Staatz, John, ”Farmers’ Incentives to Take Collective Action Via Cooperatives: A Transactions Cost Approach," in Co e ative eo : ew oache Jeffrey S. Royer, ed., Service Report 18, Agricultural Cooperative Service, USDA, July 1987. Streeter, Deborah H. and others, "Information Technology, Coordination, and Competitiveness in the Food and Agribusiness Sector,” Amefieamiqpmnlpf We. December 1991. 1467. Sun Diamond Growers, Inc., Sun Diamond Gmwen Spring 1982. Sun Diamond Growers, Inc., Sun Diamond Gzowen Fall 1987. Sun Diamond Growers, Inc., Sun Diamond Qmwer, Spring 1992. Wu, Ming-Wu, ”Supply and Demand Relationships for Tart Cherries in Michigan with Projections to 1990,” Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State University, 1976. Table 36. Tart Cherry Market Supply With and Without 261 APPENDIX A Use of the Federal Marketing Order, 1972-1975 1Out of 42.6 million pounds originally placed in the storage reserve pool, 21.0 million were eventually sold to the USDA for feeding programs. Out of the the 21.6 million that remained in the reserve pool, 16.6 million were released in spring 1981. ’l‘he remainder was sold to USDA school lunch program. 3Released the following fall and spring. Sources: 1972 carryin stocks from N n i r Fri n N Ann Reporting Board, SRS, USDA. Other figures from Red Tag Qherries grep Stagisgiee l January 1975, Crop Year of Marketing Order Use il 1972 1975 I 1980J 1984 l 1985 : ----Millions of lbs. (raw product equivalent)--- Crop Size 311.7 290.5 218.1 271.6 286.2 - Fresh Utilization 6.2 7.2 6.3 8.0 7.6 ; - Non-marketing order abandonment 19.8 39.4 1.9 13.6 6.0 II = New Crop Supply for Processing 284.9 243.9 209.9 250.0 272.6 L + Frozen Carryin Stocks 44.1 41.1 24.3 12.8 44.4 i + Canned Carryin Stocks 11.2 2.7 3.9 0.3 4.5 . = Market Supply w/o Market Order 340.2 287.7 238.1 263.1 321.5 ll . - M.O. Storage Pool 19.1 27.0 42.61 31.62 12.5 ll + M.O. Storage Pool Release 14.3 27.03 16.7 8.3 0 ll . - M.O. Secondary Mkt. Diversion 0 0 0 1.8 3.4 l - M.O. Non-harvest diversion 22.0 5.0 1.9 1.0 0.6 g = Market Supply with Market Order 313.4 282.7 2103 237.0 305.0 mm Red Tart Cherry Growers Committee, Michigan Agricultural C00perative Marketing Association, Inc. (crop data: p.1; stocks data: p.19, Table 10 and p.24, Table 17; reserve pool data: p.26, Table 19). Additional reserve pool and secondary market diversion data from B k E ' l i n 1 Makeging Enlig pi Qhem Administrative Beard (Table 3, 'Tart Cherry Marketing Order Effects on Supplies,” p. 21). 262 Table 37. Tart Cherry Supply in Years Following Marketing Order Use, With and Without Market Order Use in 1972, 1975, 1980 F-__ Year Following 1: Marketing Order Use 1973 I 1976 I 1981 Mill. lbs.(raw prod.equiv.) Crop Size 175.2 146.6 134.6 - Production Abandonment 1.2 0 0.4 - Fresh Utilization 5.2 4.4 4.0 = New Crop Supply for Processing 168.8 142.2 130.2 + Frozen Carryin Stocks 21.71 30.6 9.52 + Canned Carryin Stocks 0.4 2.2 3.6 ’ = Market Supply w/o Market Order 190.9 175.0 143.3 , + M.O. Storage Pool Release 8.4 0 4.3 = Market Supply with Market Order 182.5 175.0 147.6 121.7 million in frozen carryover is calculated from July 1 stocks of 30.1 (Table 17) minus subseqent reserve pool release of 8.4. 29.5 frozen carryover figure calculated from July 1 stocks of 35.4 (Table 17) minus 21.6 (subsequent USDA sale) minus 4.3 (1981 reserve pool sales). Source: e a Cherries C o Stat' t' d a et al is 99 Red Tart Cherry Growers Committee, Michigan Agricultural Marketing Association, Inc. (crop data: p. 1, stocks data: p. 19, Table 10 and p. 24, Table 19).