v. -‘< R A" ~. .' -A..'-s l IE3;- «4 r "revamp $24“ w" . ,; » A“. l ” fi;,r\fi. , “wait? ‘-‘“ ‘xug‘m. v.9 "is ’ a v . 3—: #~ P" 1" - :‘»;J.,. - ‘6 . -: “ u . . 1 . ‘a "f ’ y». \ :3. ‘ a. *fig. 1- 9" ‘v'é {cam Nix , ‘ ., 1,11%" ' w’xfi" TI ‘ 1“ .g n" 3%“ ' ‘ _ tee/{act , . I ~' at”: 1-1.3 ~ - “3" w” . v."’ gg‘Ef’a-‘éh a £4 _ ;::\_— 3". " k A." «WWW fiwg' ' ‘ ‘3' 1' Jflnr $34" I .‘ 2 i. .,. 1.3+: Me I RARIE ltllllllllllllllllllllllllllljlllll 31293 0104617 6 This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Parallel Processing of Satisfaction Formation: An Empirical Analysis of Competitive Alternatives presented by Robert D. Mackoy has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Business Administration we Major pr ssor Date AUQUSt 4, 1994 MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 LIBRARY Mlchlgan State University rue: ll RETURN BOXtomnovothbMouflunywrm TOAVOID FlNESrottmonorbdmdutodm. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE MSU lommmmd Oppomlnlylmtltwon W1 PARALLEL PROCESSING OF SATISFACTION FORMATION: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF COMPETITIVE ALTERNATIVES By Robert D. Mackoy A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Marketing and Logistics 1994 ABSTRACT PARALLEL PROCESSING OF SATISFACTION FORMATION: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF COMPETITIVE ALTERNATIVES By Robert D. Mackoy The notion of competition is an integral element of the choice process. Yet postchoice processes, such as satisfaction formation, are modeled in a manner inconsistent with the competitive reality in which they, too, occur. Current models of satisfaction formation focus exclusively on the single, chosen product while assuming that evaluations of competing products are no longer salient. This dissertation reviews the satisfaction literature in marketing and presents a model of satisfaction formation which explicitly considers competitive alternatives. Parallel yet interrelated paths of satisfaction formation are hypothesized to lead to satisfaction with the competing targets (both the choice and nonchoice alternatives) and then to overall satisfaction. Also addressed are issues related to postchoice processing. In this dissertation, dissatisfied consumers are hypothesized to process more extensively than do satisfied consumers. The relative importance of predictive expectations, desires, attitudes and disconfirmation of expectations as antecedents of satisfaction are investigated within this framework. The research hypotheses are tested using data from the 1992 US. presidential election within a longitudinal research design. Using primarily LISREL two-group analyses, support is found for each of the following research hypotheses: 0 Research hypothesis 1: Multiple targets of satisfaction may remain salient post choice during satisfaction formation. 0 Research hypothesis 2: The processing paths associated with each of the multiple targets of satisfaction are interrelated, i.e. there are cross-over effects. 0 Research hypothesis 3: Dissatisfied subjects process more extensively or completely than do satisfied subjects. 0 Research hypothesis 4: Desires have a greater impact on satisfaction formation than do expectations. The dissertation has significant implications for the satisfaction formation literature. Specifically, all current models of satisfaction formation focus on the single product or service of interest; yet this dissertation shows that, in a competitive environment, alternative products or services mt chosen may also impact satisfaction formation. One conceptual implication is that the fundamental structure of future satisfaction models should be altered to include competitive alternatives. In addition, managerial implications include the necessity of revising both satisfaction monitoring methodologies and the strategies for managing key marketing mix variables. Copyrighted by Robert D. Mackoy 1994 DEDICATION This work is loving dedicated to my wife, Tina, whose support, patience and effort made it possible both to contemplate and to complete this endeavor. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I gratefully acknowledge the contributions of my dissertation committee, both collectively and individually. Professor Roger Calantone and Professor Bixby Cooper each provided helpful comments and guidance early in the proposal stage, and each provided useful comments on successive drafts. Professor Richard Spreng was extremely generous with his expertise in the area of consumer satisfaction and with his time: he spent countless hours with me and with each version of this dissertation. He also provided valuable insights about the early years of an academic career. To my chair, Professor Cornelia Droge, I am especially grateful. Her masterful guidance at each stage of this work - encouraging, discussing, criticizing, challenging, analyzing -- kept me moving in the right direction. She has taught me how to engage the research process with curiosity, with thoughtfulness, with thoroughness, with tenacity, with wonder. For this, for expertly managing the committee, and for sharing her thoughts about thriving in an academic career, I am truly indebted. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ...................................................... xi List of Figures .................................................... xiii I. Introduction and Overview ................................... 1 H. Logic of the thesis: Relation to consumer behavior ....... 2 I-2. Logic of the thesis: Theoretical support .................. 6 [—3. Logic of the thesis: Example ............................ 7 [-4. Four research themes and expected theoretical contributions ......................................... 10 I-S. Context of the empirical test ........................... 12 [-6. Managerial implications ............................... 14 II. Satisfaction Literature in Marketing 11-]. Introduction ......................................... 19 11-1.]. Scope of the literature review ................. 19 II-l.2. "Traditional" satisfaction model framework ..... 24 11-2. Satisfaction and its measurement ....................... Z7 II-3. Antecedent constructs and their measurement ........... 42 11-3 . 1. Expectation .................................. 42 lI-3.2. Desires ..................................... 56 II-3.3. Attitudes .................................... 60 Il—3.4. Perceived performance ....................... 61 II-3.S. Disconfirmation ............................. 67 11-4. Principle relationships among constructs ............... 78 “-4.1. Antecedents of perceived performance: Expectations, Desires, and Attitudes ............. 78 vii II-4.2. Antecedents of disconfirmation: Expectations, Desires, Attitudes, and Perceived Performance ................................ 81 II-4.3. Antecedents of satisfaction: Expectations, Desires, Attitudes, Perceived Performance and Disconfirmation ............. 86 II-S Other relevant topics .................................. 103 II—S. 1. Model complexity - Structural .................. 103 II-5.1. Model complexity - Processes ................... 106 II-6 Summary of literature review ........................... 108 Key Theoretical Issues Addressed ............................... 114 III-1 . Introduction .......................................... 114 111-2. Thesis themes, research hypotheses, and testable hypotheses ........................................... 115 III-2.1. Theme No. 1: Multiple targets ................... 115 III-2.2. Theme No. 2: Parallel paths with cross-over effects ....................................... 124 III-2.3. Theme No. 3: Differential processing due to ultimate level of satisfaction .................. 129 III-2.4. Theme No. 4: Importance of desires versus expectations in satisfaction formation ......... 138 III-3 . Models to test hypotheses .............................. 141 Ill-3. 1. Election outcome satisfaction model ............ 141 III—3.2. Campaign process satisfaction model .......... 143 Method ..................................................... 14S IV-l. Data collection and timing ............................. 145 IV-Z. Operationalization of key constructs .................... 147 IV-2.1. Election Outcome Satisfaction Model - Operationalization of key constructs ........... 149 IV-2.2. Campaign Process Satisfaction Model - Operationalization of key constructs ............ 156 IV-3. Other relevant variables ............................... 159 V. Results ...................................................... 162 V—l. V-Z. General description of subsamples ...................... 162 Results of the Election Outcome Satisfaction Model ........ 166 V-2.1. Differences between the two groups (EOSM) ..... 166 V-2.2. Results of the EOSM two-group LISREL analysis . . 170 V-2.3. EOSM two-group results related to research hypothesis #1 ................................ 174 V-2.4. EOSM two-group results related to research hypothesis #2 ................................ 177 V-2.5. EOSM two-group results related to research hypothesis #3 ................................ 183 V-2.6. EOSM two-group results related to research hypothesis #4 ................................ 184 V-2.7. Summary of EOSM results ...................... 186 Results of the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model ........ 186 V-3.1. Differences between the two groups (CPSM) ..... 187 V—3.2. Results of the CPSM two-group LISREL analysis . . 187 V-3.3. CPSM two-group results related to research hypothesis #1 ................................ 191 V-3.4. Additional observations from the CPSM two- group analysis ............................... 201 Results of the EOSM LISREL analysis of satisfied Clinton voters and dissatisfied Bush voters ....................... 202 V—4.1. Analysis of EOSM with satisfied and dissatisfied V-4.2. V-4.3. voters -- results related to research hypothesis #3 ................................ 203 Analysis of EOSM with satisfied and dissatisfied voters -- results related to research hypothesis #1 ................................ 208 Analysis of EOSM with satisfied and dissatisfied voters -- results related to research hypothesis #2 ................................ 209 ix V-S. Results of the CPSM correlation analysis of satisfied versus dissatisfied voters ............................... 210 V-6. Summary of results relating to the research hypotheses . . . 220 VI. Discussion and Implications ................................... 224 VI-l. The competitive model of satisfaction formation .......... 225 VI-Z. Differential processing ................................ 232 VI-3. Total effects of desires versus expectations ............... 237 Vl-4. Other findings in relation to past research ............... 241 Vl-4.1. The relationship of expectations to disconfirmation and to satisfaction ............. 241 VI-4.2. Disconfirmation .............................. 244 v1-4.3. Attitudes ..................................... 24s Vl-4.4. Context of the research ........................ 247 VI-S. Limitations ............................................ 248 VI-6. Concluding remarks ................................... 250 List of References .................................................. 252 \DQVO‘M-fi-WNt—b r—tr-fii—‘h—it—i Ari-‘O 15 16 17 18 19 21 LIST OF TABLES Measures of Satisfaction in Empirical Studies ................... 32 Specific Measures of Satisfaction ............................... 34 Measures of Expectations ...................................... 45 Specific Measures of Expectations .............................. 47 Specific Measures of Performance .............................. 63 Measures of Disconfirmation in Empirical Studies ................ 68 Specific Measures of Disconfirmation ........................... 69 Classification of Studies Which Include Disconfirmation ........... 71 Antecedents of Performance--Relative Importance ............... 79 Antecedents of Disconfirmation—Standards Disconfirmed .......... 82 Antecedents of Disconfirmation-~Relative Importance ............ 83 Characteristics of Studies Testing Antecedents of Satisfaction ...... 87 Antecedents of Satisfaction-Relative Importance ................ 9o Characteristics of Disconfirmation and Satisfaction Measures Used in Satisfaction Models ..................................... 95 Operationalization of Constructs - Timing of Measurements for Each Model ............................................... 148 Operationalization of Constructs - Election Outcome Satisfaction Model ....................................................... 155 Operationalization of Constructs -- Campaign Process Satisfaction Model ....................................................... 158 Operationalization of Constructs -- Campaign Process Satisfaction Model ....................................................... 161 Organization of Chapter 5 ..................................... 163 Description of the Sample --Differences Between Clinton and Bush Subsamples on Selected Variables ......................... 165 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model -Means and Standard Deviations of Each Group ...................................... 167 xi LIST OF TABLES (continued) 22 23 24 26 '3 31 32 33 35 39 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model «Components of Attitude Towards the Candidate ........................................ 169 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model «Correlation Matrices ........ 171 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model «Within Group Indicators of Fit ........................................................ 172 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model «Unstandardized Estimates and Standard Errors of Structural Paths ......................... 176 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model «Common Metric Standardized Solution ......................................... 178 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model «Psi Matrix Results .......... 182 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model «Total Effects of Expectations versus Desires .................................... 185 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model «Means and Standard Deviations of Each Group ...................................... 188 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model «Correlation Matrices ...... 189 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model «Within Group Indicators of Fit ............................................. . ........... 1 92 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model «Unstandardized Estimates and Standard Errors of Structural Paths ................ 195 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model «Psi Matrix Results ......... 196 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model «Common Metric Standardized Solution ......................................... 198 EOSM « Unstandardized Estimates and Standard Errors of Structural Paths -- Satisfied Clinton Voters versus All Clinton Voters ................................................ 204 EDSM « Unstandardized Estimates and Standard Errors of Structural Paths « Dissatisfied Bush Voters versus All Bush Voters .................................................. 205 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model -- Summary of Differences in Model Results Using All/Satisfied Clinton Voters and All/ Dissatisfied Bush Voters ......................... 206 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model «Subgroup Correlation Matrices ..................................................... 213 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model «Summary of Subgroup Correlation Analyses ......................................... 217 xii 10 11 12 13 14 15 l6 17 LIST OF FIGURES Pre-Decision versus Post-Decision Models ........................ 4 Pre-Decision versus Post-Decision « Proposed Model .............. 8 Classification of Satisfaction Formation Constructs from the Traditional Model ..................................... 26 Targets of Satisfaction: Variations in the Traditional Model ........ 116 Hypothesized Relationships: Satisfaction with Choice, Satisfaction with Nonchoice, and Overall Satisfaction ........................ 118 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model: Theme No. 1 Research Hypothesis ................................................... 120 Hypothesized Effects of Satisfaction Antecedents Regarding Separate Targets on Overall Satisfaction ......................... 122 Hypothesized Paths in the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model for Testing the Multiple Targets Research Hypothesis ............. 123 Traditional Model: Different Targets Require Parallel and Unrelated Paths ........................................... 125 Hypothesized Model: Parallel Paths and Cross-over Effects ......... 127 Hypothesized Relationships Among Key Antecedent Variables and Satisfaction ...................................... 131 Hypothesized Paths for Satisfied Versus Dissatisfied Voters ......... 133 Hypothesized Paths in the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model for Those Dissatisfied with the Process ..................... 135 Hypothesized Paths in the Campaign Process Satisfaction Those Satisfied with the Process . . ............................... 137 Complete Election Outcome Satisfaction Model ..................... 142 Complete Campaign Process Satisfaction Model .................... 144 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model -- Distribution of Standardized Residuals .......................................... 173 xiii LIST OF FIGURES (continued) 18 19 20 21 Results: Election Outcome Satisfaction Model -- Clinton Voters ............................................ Results: Election Outcome Satisfaction Model « Bush Voters .............................................. Campaign Process Satisfaction Model « Distribution of Standardized Residuals ................................... Results: Campaign Process Satisfaction Model « Clinton Voters ............................................. Results: Campaign Process Satisfaction Model « Bush Voters ............................................... Overall Satisfaction with Process (CPSM) ..................... xiv 179 180 193 199 211 Chapter I Introduction, Problem Statement, and Expected Contributions 1. Introduction and Overview Since marketing scholars first began to investigate consumer satisfaction, the literature has been dominated by two conceptualizations regarding the satisfaction formation process. These widely accepted but rarely discussed conceptualizations are that: 1) satisfaction formation occurs post-purchase relative to a single relevant product or service target (the "choice") and is unrelated to alternatives considered but not chosen (the "nonchoice"); 2) there is a single underlying satisfaction formation process that operates across individuals and usage contexts. This dissertation questions these two conceptualizations by addressing four general research themes: (1) multiple targets (both "choices" and "nonchoices"); (2) interrelated processes of satisfaction formation relative to the multiple targets; (3) differential processing for satisfied versus dissatisfied consumers; (4) expectations versus desires as antecedents of satisfaction formation. The first three of these themes address directly the widely accepted conceptualizations enumerated above. In this introductory chapter, the logic behind the four research themes of the dissertation is introduced in relation to the field of consumer behavior as a whole, and then is illustrated using examples based on common consumer experiences. Next, the four themes are briefly presented along with the theoretical contributions each is expected to make. The context within which the four research themes will be analyzed is then presented. Managerial implications of the dissertation are presented next. Finally, the structure of this dissertation is summarized. I- l . Logic of the thesis: Relation to consumer behavior Marketing scholars have long recognized the centrality of the concept of satisfaction to their discipline. Early in the twentieth century, it was recognized that the drive to satisfy desires coupled with the reality of limited resources resulted in the need to choose from among competing alternatives. For example, one early marketing text states: "No one can satisfy all of his wants. People are never entirely satisfied Because the human being has many wants and only a part of them can be satisfied, choice must be made The consumer undoubtedly finds the greatest satisfaction when his choices accord most fully with all of the factors enumerated" (Nystrom, 1929, pages 51, 72). In other words, consumer satisfaction and consumer decision-making were recognized as being interdependent. As the discipline evolved, marketing scholars used taxonomical distinctions to help analyze the structure and function of marketing processes. Alderson (1957) bisected consumer behavior into buying processes and consuming processes en route to developing his functionalist theoretical perspective. The distinction between buying and consuming as discussed by Alderson continues to be useful when looking at the field of consumer behavior as a whole. "Buying" refers to the information-processing aspects of consumer decisions and consumer choice, while "consuming" refers to often- neglected but "....equally important experiential aspects of consumption" (Holbrook and Hirshman 1982, page 139). Westbrook and Oliver (1991) go so far as to consider this distinction to be an "....emerging dialectic between decision processes and experiential perspectives of the study of consumer behavior" (p. 84). Study of consumer satisfaction is one topic which resides primarily in the post-decision, consuming realm of consumer behavior. Traditional models of satisfaction formation typically regard consumer choice as a given and specify satisfaction to be a function of antecedents such as expectation, desire, attitude, perceived performance, and disconfirmation relative to the choice already made. Thus, most satisfaction models have been structured and tested in a manner consistent with Alderson's (195 7) distinctions, that is, with consumption as totally separate from the "buying" process. However, should the fact that it is possible to distinguish between the purchase decision and consumption imply that it is desirable to study each as if they are unrelated? Consider the implications of the "emerging dialectic" as illustrated in Figure 1. The consumer considers purchasing one of three alternative products or services. To explain how the choice is made, numerous models have been proposed, tested and supported. Often such choice processes include intensive information manipulation on an attribute-by-attribute basis comparing expected characteristics or performance levels. Such comparisons are made with the consumer's internal standards and/ or with the characteristics and performance levels of the other alternatives. The end result of this "buying" process is a selected alternative, in this case, Alternative B. Consumer satisfaction, as part of the "consuming process," is universally modeled as a response or a judgment of the consumption experience related only to Alternative B. Expectations, desires, attitudes, perceived performance, Pre-Decision Post-Decision Afi Sat' fact' 0v all 3% wit: ch02: * Satisfaction Cfi Traditional Choice Models: Satisfaction Models: Alternatives A, B, and C are Only the antecedent constructs in relation considered and comparatively to the choice (here, alternative 8) are evaluated. Expectations and considered relevant. desires are formed relative to all three alternatives. Figure l Pre-Decision Versus Post—Decision Models and disconfirmation related to Alternative B are considered sufficient to understand satisfaction with the consumption experience. In other words, satisfaction is modeled as a single process related to a single target. When one considers the inten_sive choice processing which involved Alternatives A and C in addition to B, it seems unreasonable to assume that those alternatives not selected become totally irrelevant to post-choice sgt_i§_f_2_1ction formation processes. Expectations, desires and attitudes regarding Alternative B evolved in relation to expectations, desires and attitudes regarding the two other alternatives. Likewise, in some usage contexts, the perceived performance of Alternatives A and C may influence the consumption experience of the consumer who selected Alternative B, especially if the consumer is dissatisfied with B. Some researchers (e.g., Cadotte, Woodruff and Jenkins 1987; Spreng and Olshavsky 1993) have used nonchoice alternatives as standards of comparison in satisfaction formation processes; however, the "comparison" is thought to occur at a distinct, single point (e.g., disconfirmation) in a total process which s_tfll focuses only on the choice alternative. In summary, it is unrealistic to assume that intensively "processed" but unselected alternatives ("nonchoices") have no impact on satisfaction formation regarding the selected alternative (the "choice"). Given that many consumer decisions of interest to marketers occur in a competitive context « one in which alternatives exist, information is abundant, processing is encouraged, and risk is involved « it becomes clear that the satisfaction literature has not developed a satisfaction model which explicitly considers competition. [-2. Logic of the thesis: Theoretical support While marketing scholars have neglected the relationship between consumer decision making and satisfaction formation, theoretical support for such a relationship is apparent from two other sources. In A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance, Festinger (1957) explicitly recognizes that dissonance can be created by the simple act of choosing one alternative while rejecting others. He states: "....There will be some cognitive elements corresponding to the positive aspects of the unchosen alternative and some elements corresponding to the negative aspects of the chosen alternative which will be dissonant with the cognition of having chosen one particular alternative..." (p. 36). Thus, Festinger provides a theoretical link for hypothesizing that nonchoice alternatives may continue to have an impact on consumers' post- choice experiences. Although Festinger's analysis is limited to the period following the choice and prior to actual consumption (p. 43), there is no logical reason for concluding that dissonance can not extend into post- consumption processes. Theoretical support for the major premise of this dissertation may also be found in regret theory from the field of economics. Loomes and Sugden (1982) offered regret theory as a parsimonious alternative explanation of some types of observed "non-rational" consumer choice behavior. Numerous scholars (e.g., Kahneman and Tversky 1979) have demonstrated that consumers systematically violate commonly accepted axioms of choice under uncertainty. Rather than construct elaborate explanations of such behavior, Loomes and Sugden (1982) question the axioms themselves. Their theory is based on the notion that consumer choice is not "....independent of the nature and combination of actions simultaneously rejected..." (p. 82). In their theory, the anticipation of regret (and/ or "rejoicing") is combined with factors derived from conventional utility theory. The entire constellation of alternatives in the choice set is evaluated in terms of expectations following the decision. For example, using the situation depicted in Figure 1, traditional choice theory would state "choosing alternative B is preferred to choosing alternatives A or C." Regret theory would state that "choosing alternative B and simultaneously rejecting alternatives A and C is preferred to 1) choosing alternative A and simultaneously rejecting alternatives B and C or 2) choosing alternative C and simultaneously rejecting alternatives A and B." The rationale for the latter framework is that consumers anticipate (expect) regret from choices not made and factor that anticipation into their decision. For our purposes, the important point is the implication that consumers develop expectations regarding their future responses to nonchoice alternatives. Thus, it is logical to hypothesize that nonchoice alternatives may remm salient in both buying and consuming processes. I-3 . Logic of the thesis: Example In this dissertation, the relevance of Alternatives A and C, the unselected alternatives, will be explored. Specifically, it will be proposed that multiple "targets" and parallel satisfaction processing paths for these targets are relevant to satisfaction formation (see Figure 2). The logic of multiple targets and parallel processing of satisfaction formation can be illustrated with the following example. Consider a husband and wife who buy new cars at approximately the same time. She buys a Geo Prizm and he buys a Toyota Tercel. The wife was confronted with an attempted "bait and switch" maneuver and dealt with a Pre-Decision Post-Decision Satisfaction Afi + w/ nonchoice B—->fl-> ll Satisfaction Overall w/ choice Satisfaction é Satisfaction C + w/ nonchoic Proposed Choice Models Satisfaction Model Constructs relevant to both choice ("B") and nonchoice ("A" and "C") alternatives affect choice satisfaction processes and overall satisfaction. Figure 2 Pre-Decision Versus Post-Decision -- Proposed Model salesman who tried to add on several new costs at the closing. Still, the wife remained firm in her position and ultimately obtained the car she wanted at the expected price. Her husband, on the other hand, experienced no problems or surprises during the entire negotiation and closing process, and in fact was offered several minor services (free of charge) which had not been expected. During the first year of ownership, the wife's car needed minor repairs on two occasions to correct a manufacturing defect. Both events were covered by warranty. The husband's car did not need any repairs. At the end of the second year, the wife's car began to exhibit minor rust spots; the husband's car did not. Though the wife is, in general, satisfied with her car, that satisfaction is diminished because of her "experiences" with the husband's car. The husband's satisfaction with his car is intensified because of his experience with his wife's car. In other words, satisfaction with the choice is partly the result of expectations, desires, performance, and disconfirmation associated with the nonchoice. Note that this experience is n_o_t_ simply the result of having another substitute comparison standard as some have suggested. Rather it is the result of parallel processing along the entire satisfaction formation process. The husband's overall satisfaction with his transportation experience is influenced not only by his satisfaction with the Tercel, but also by his satisfaction with the Prizm. His satisfaction with the Prizm is determined in part by his expectations, desires, performance perceptions, and disconfirmation related to the Prism as well as by the these same constructs related to the Tercel. (This illustrates the first and second themes of the dissertation«see Section I-4.) Because the husband is satisfied with his car, he does not think much about his original expectations, desires, or attitudes, nor does he think about 10 whether these pre-purchase expectations, desires, and attitudes have been supported in his experience with the car. Because he is satisfied, he can move about his daily routine without giving the car much thought. On the other hand, his wife is mildly dissatisfied with her car. This dissatisfaction "gnaws" at her. It bothers her that although she spent $800 more for her car, she is less satisfied than her husband is with his car. She recalls her original expectations, desires and attitudes: "What did I expect? Were my expectations unreasonably high or is the performance really worse than it should be? All I really wanted was a trouble-free car; was that unreasonable? I really believed that American car companies could once again compete with Japanese companies, but maybe my husband was right ....". She replays her decision process in her mind, partly because she doesn't want to repeat her "mistake" and partly because her dissatisfaction iust bothers her. (This illustrates the third theme of the dissertation.) Upon reflection, the wife realizes that she had, to a certain extent, talked herself into believing that American cars were once again of high quality. She wanted it to be true, but in the back of her mind she expected to have a few more problems with her car than her husband had with his. When she actually experienced the problems, however, she was dissatisfied because she had desired a trouble-free car, though she had expected less. (This illustrates the fourth theme of the dissertation.) [-4. Four research themes and expected contribution Because this thesis will investigate issues pertaining to the core structure of satisfaction formation processes, it is expected to make theoretical contributions to the satisfaction literature. Each of the four themes of this ll dissertation will contribute directly to the conceptual understanding of satisfaction formation processing. In some cases, significant new structural enhancements are proposed. In other cases, discussion will address areas in which conflicting results have been obtained. Expected theoretical contributions are outlined next. (1) The potential relevance of multiple targets of satisfaction formation (i.e., choice and nonchoice) will be investigated. Current models of satisfaction formation processes universally focus on a single target, the central object or event about which satisfaction is being measured. It will be demonstrated that, at least in some situations, measuring satisfaction with multiple targets, individually and collectively, is more relevant than measuring satisfaction with a single target. Situations in which multiple targets are likely to be relevant are those in which consumers select a product or service from among a set of alternative possible choices, and have some exposure (direct or vicarious) to the performance of nonchoice alternatives. Since a large proportion of consumer decisions occur in such situations, conceptual implications of this thesis may be far reaching. (2) It will be demonstrated that the processes resulting in satisfaction/ dissatisfaction with multiple targets are parallel yet interrelated. The major implication of this finding is that the complexity of satisfaction formation processing is not adequately captured in current models of satisfaction formation. Not only should satisfaction with multiple targets be considered, but the satisfaction formation process of each target also needs to be included in satisfaction models, since the processes themselves are interrelated. 12 (3) It will be tested whether dissatisfied consumers process differently from satisfied consumers. Current satisfaction formation models do not differentiate between the actual processing of satisfied versus dissatisfied consumers. The demonstration of differential processing implies the need for using models of greater complexity, and/ or for developing a contingency processing model. (4) It will be tested whether the t_ot_al effects of desires are greater than the total effects of expectations in determining satisfaction with an important, mghly involvingevent. One could argue that desires is a future-oriented affect-based construct, just as expectation is a future-oriented cognition-based construct. If supported, the implication of this theme is that the recent trend in satisfaction literature towards an increased focus on affect should be continued or expanded. I -5 . Context of the empirical test It seems logical to expect there to be a continuum of usage contexts based on the degree to which non-selected alternatives (nonchoices) are relevant to satisfaction formation. At one extreme would be the context implied by the traditional satisfaction model (i.e., single target and single process). At the other extreme would be contexts in which all alternatives considered have significant impacts on satisfaction formation. To explore the proposition that nonchoices can have a significant impact on satisfaction formation, it makes sense to select a context in which the probability of uncovering such relationships (if they exist) is high. If it can be demonstrated that nonchoices can influence consumption experience satisfaction formation in one context, 13 then the range of contexts within which such relationships occur can be explored. The first step, however, is to demonstrate that it ga_n occur. The context for analyzing the four research themes will be the 1992 US. presidential election. An election entails many of the same characteristics as many more traditional consumer choice settings: an abundance of information, choice among alternatives, relevance of traditional antecedent constructs (e.g., expectations, desires, attitudes, etc.), persuasion attempts that can create expectations, the probability that individuals will ultimately be satisfied or dissatisfied. In addition, an election provides the potential to obtain additional benefits rarely evident in more traditional consumer behavior settings: wide variance in measures of satisfaction, wide variance in measures of desires, and clear, objective, widely perceived measures of performance (i.e., the outcome of the election). Use of the 1992 presidential election as an arena for testing and developing satisfaction theory is appropriate for at least three additional reasons: 1) Marketing of political candidates is a huge industry in its own right. Tens of millions of dollars are spent on campaigns during presidential election years, and nearly as much is spent on campaigns, research, and political strategizing during other years. The high cost of running for office is the major force behind proposed campaign finance reform legislation. Marketing research firms using established market research techniques play a prominent role in identifying target markets and effective communications program development. All the tools of advertising and public relations are utilized. The "product" (i.e., candidate) is created and modified to most closely match the wants and desires of the "consumers" (i.e., voters). Given the clear l4 role of marketing in elections, it is surprising that political campaigning is a topic seldom discussed by the marketing discipline. 2) Several topics clearly within the domain of marketing possess characteristics which parallel those of political marketing. Any situation in which few competitors compete in a zero-sum situation has similarities to election marketing. Professional sports marketing, for example, is one marketing application which may have similar satisfaction formation processes. Two teams compete head-to-head and one team wins. Fans of each team have expectations and desires before the contest, and varying degrees of disconfirmation and satisfaction following the contest. The outcome itself is generally unambiguous, and people can distinguish between the process and the outcome. Other possible parallels include governmental and organi- zational buying in which a limited number of bidders compete in a zero - sum situation. 3) Findings from this investigation may be relevant to the broad spectrum of product and service contexts because what is being investigated is the structural relationship among the antecedent constructs of satisfaction. As such, the investigation may have implications for satisfaction theory in general. In other words, because the topic of interest is the relationship among constructs, the findings may be relevant to the relationships among satisfaction constructs in general. I-6. Managerial implications Top managers understand the importance of satisfaction formation processes in determining corporate success. For example, Jack Welch, successful CEO of General Electric, states: "Too often we measure everything 15 and understand nothing. The three most important things you need to measure in a business are customer satisfaction, employee satisfaction and cash flow. If you're growing customer satisfaction, global market share is sure to grow too" (Tichy and Sherman 1993, p. 88). Conversely, managers recognize that dissatisfaction has serious repercussions. Numerous consequences of consumer dissatisfaction have been documented including loss of repeat business, low employee moral, negative "halo" effect on other aspects of the business, and negative word-of-mouth communications (Albrecht and Zemke 1985). The cost of adding a new customer is significantly higher than retaining an existing customer and even small decreases in customer defection rates can have a major impact on company profits (Reichheld and Sasser 1990). Given the increasing openness of global markets, foreign firms which have specialized in satisfying customers will enjoy competitive advantages over U.S. firms which have not. Because this dissertation questions the core structure of satisfaction formation processes, results are expected to have numerous implications for managerial application. 1) If the parallel satisfaction processing framework is supported, managers may have to alter their strategies for increasing/maintaining consumer satisfaction. They will have to consider that consumer satisfaction with their product or service is, in part, determined by consumer satisfaction with competitors' products or services. Also, they will consider the implications of the fact that consumer satisfaction with competitors' goods and services is at least partially determined by customer satisfaction with their goods and services. This represents the simple, but critical recognition that satisfaction formation processes. too, occur within a compatitive environment. 16 Producing high quality products at a fair price is not the only determinant of satisfaction even among one's own customers. Of course, much more research will be needed to establish that such parallel processing occurs in the context of consumer and durable goods. The exact nature of the "cross-over" effects in various contexts will also need to be specified. 2) Support for the parallel processing framework would imply managers should immediately begin to alter the way they monitor customer satisfaction. Most firms which monitor satisfaction currently collect measurements only with regard to their own products; those firms which do collect information related to competitors' products collect only summary information instead of information relevant to the satisfaction process. Satisfaction information with regard to competitors will help in determining the degree to which parallel processing occurs in a particular industry, and if it does occur, will provide guidelines for managing satisfaction formation. 3) If it is determined that satisfied versus dissatisfied consumers arrive at their ultimate level of satisfaction/dissatisfaction differently, efforts to promote or discourage specific kjn_ds of processing may be effective in managing satisfaction formation. 4) By clarifying the relative importance of expectations versus desires in the satisfaction formation process, firms will have a clearer idea of how to promote and advertise their products and services. Again, specific findings from studiesconducted in specific industries will be necessary to determine ideal applications. However, this dissertation is a necessary first step. 5) If this research effort is successful, at least part of its success will be due to the wide variance of the satisfaction measures. Thus, the dissertation will demonstrate the practical implications of developing satisfaction 17 measures which exhibit variance. Currently, many satisfaction monitoring efforts in industry are ineffective because satisfaction levels are consistently high. This causes two problems. First, it is impossible to measure any improvements which do occur because satisfaction levels cannot increase. Thus, the usefulness of such measures as a factor in determining manager bonuses, for example, becomes insignificant. Some firms have attempted to address this by measuring proxies for dissatisfaction such as customer complaints. However, such a practice is dangerous because then the manager has an incentive to minimize or suppress complaints even though complaints are a valuable source of information. Second, relationships between potential antecedents of satisfaction and dissatisfaction become extremely difficult to identify or monitor. Thus, managers are unable to establish priorities among the factors responsible for satisfaction. Obviously, this reduces the probability that resources will be optimally distributed. Therefore, simply increasing variance in the satisfaction measure can lead to improvements in the usefulness of satisfaction measurement. 6) Clarification of the relationship between attitudes and desires, and their relative importance in the satisfaction formation process, will help managers make decisions regarding allocation of resources among efforts designed to alter desires (or perceptions of desires congruence) versus those designed to improve attitudes. [-7. Structure of the dissertation Following this introductory chapter, the dissertation is organized as follows. Chapter 11 contains a review of the traditional satisfaction literature with a focus on the constructs used and the relationships among constructs. 18 Chapter 111 provides the formal development of the research and testable hypotheses associated with the four general research themes of this dissertation. Chapter IV contains a description of the design, data collection and analytical methods used to test the research hypotheses. Chapter V presents results of the empirical investigation, and Chapter VI contains the discussion of results, limitations, and implications for future research. Chapter II Satisfaction Literature in Marketing II. Introduction The purpose of this chapter is to review the relevant satisfaction literature (within the limits described below) in order to develop a thorough understanding of the current state of satisfaction formation processing models in marketing. The review will be broken into four broad topic areas. In the first, the conceptualization and Operationalization of commonly used constructs will be analyzed. The second will focus on empirical findings regarding key relationships among the antecedent constructs. The third topic area will focus on the relationship between antecedent constructs and satisfaction. The final topic area will examine other relevant findings not explicitly involving common constructs. Throughout this chapter, distinctions will be drawn between how a construct is conceptualized and how it is measured, as the two often appear to be different. These differences may be responsible for at least some of the confusion and inconsistencies found in the satisfaction literature. II-1.1 Scope of the literature review This review is necessarily limited both with regard to concepts addressed and to sources reviewed. The purpose of this section is to make the limits explicit. Thus, the following are discussed in this section: (1) sources reviewed; (2) the political science literature; and (3) goods versus services marketing. 19 20 Sources reviewed With regard to sources utilized, this review of theoretical and empirical contributions to the satisfaction literature is delimited as follows. First the review will focp§ on contributions from ma_rl_ disconfirmation -> satisfaction. The review which follows begins with a conceptual and empirical analysis of "satisfaction" as a construct (Section II-2). Next, the pre- performance and post-performance constructs are examined (Section II-3); then, relationships among the constructs are reviewed (Section II-4). Additional constructs not generally considered part of the traditional satisfaction model are reviewed (Section II-S). Finally, the major points of the chapter are summarized (Section II-6). II-2. Satisfaction and its measurement Satisfaction of consumer needs and wants is arguably the central theme of marketing as a discipline. Therefore, it is surprising that serious attempts to define satisfaction both theoretically and empirically did not begin until the late 19608. Two related forces may be credited with the rise of interest in satisfaction as a topic worthy of investigation. First, the rise of consumer behavior as an identifiable subdiscipline within marketing brought the perspectives and methods of psychology and social psychology to marketing. The focus on understanding and predicting the perceptions, attitudes and behaviors of individual consumers resulted in the identification of satisfaction as a key construct (Hunt 1977). Second, one of the periodic revivals of 28 consumerism as a social and political force occurred during this period. Consumer satisfaction became a salient public policy issue due to widespread perceptions that companies were not responsive to consumer demands and that the federal government was overly supportive of business interests at the expense of consumers. Perhaps not surprising is the emphasis on consumer dissatisfaction and complaining behavior which resulted from this reincarnation Of consumerism. Cpgnitive versus affective content Early conceptualizations of satisfaction in the marketing literature described satisfaction in cognitive terms (Engel, Kollet, and Blackwell 1973; Howard and Sheth 1969). For example, Howard and Sheth (1969) define satisfaction as "....the buyer's cognitive state of being adéquately or inadequately rewarded for the sacrifices he has undergone" (p. 145). The traditional satisfaction formation model treats the process as being primarily cognitive, while the satisfaction construct itself is generally perceived to have definite affective overtones. Only recently have affect- based processes been proposed to help explain satisfaction. This may be due in part to the recent theoretical advances made in understanding affect (e.g., Izard 1984). Zajonc (1980) indicates that though the importance of affect has long been recognized, empirical and theoretical emphasis on cognitive psychology has dominated the discipline of psychology. Given the close relationship of psychology and marketing, especially in the consumer behavior school (Sheth, Gardner, and Garrett 1988), it is not surprising that early satisfaction researchers sought cognitive antecedents of satisfaction. 29 Within marketing, the role of affect in satisfaction is first discussed by Hunt (1977) who states that affective responses to a product experience follow the formation of satisfaction via cognitive processes. Westbrook (1980) raises the question of whether affect enters the satisfaction process prior to or concurrent with satisfaction. He states "....affective influences do not, of course, deny the role of cognitive processes such as expectancy confirmation or disconfirmation, but rather combine with them in the determination of consumer satisfaction" (p. 50). Customer satisfaction, then, is viewed as a combination of cognitive and affective elements in an overall evaluation of a product. Others also believe that satisfaction is a general, overall feeling. For example, Westbrook and Newman ( 1978) state "Satisfaction typically is conceived as the extent to which consumers feel subjectively pleased with their ownership and usage of products" (p. 456). Likewise, Cadotte, Woodruff and Jenkins ( 1987) define and measure satisfaction as a summary, affective C 0118th t. Dimensionality The dimensionality of satisfaction has been questioned (Swan and Combs 1976; Maddox 1981) and the issue remains unresolved (Yi 1990). The primary issue is whether satisfaction is a unidimensional construct (e.g., with anchors of "completely dissatisfied" and "completely satisfied") or two separate constructs, one being "level of satisfaction" and the other being "level of dissatisfaction." The two-factor conceptualization is based on Herzberg's Two- Factor Theory (Herzberg, Mausner, and Snyderman 1959) and derives support from two basic observations. First, consumers appear capable of being both 30 satisfied and dissatisfied at the same time and therefore the two constructs must be at least somewhat independent. Second, consumers who are asked to recall both satisfying and dissatisfying experiences recall different "levels" of phenomena for describing why they are satisfied versus dissatisfied (Maddox 1981). Only equivocal empirical evidence has been found to support the two- construct conceptualization. Swan and Combs (1976) found weak preliminary support. Their study was replicated by Maddox (1981) using larger samples of customers drawn from multiple industries. Maddox found little support for the two-factor conceptualization, and concludes that such a conceptualization also yields implications which run contrary to common sense. Until recently, support for the two factor conceptualization has been derived almost exclusively from studies using a single methodology: the "critical incidents" method described above. An alternative explanation of the findings yielded by this method is possible. Briefly, it is possible that the satisfaction construct is unidimensional, but, given that satisfied and dissatisfied consumers may process differently, theLremember different kinds of factors as being responsible for their ultimate level of sagsfamp. Because the critical incidents method requires consumers to "retrace" their process, it is not surprising that their responses are qualitatively different. Recent evidence from Babin et a1 (1993) provide stronger empirical support for a two-dimensional conceptualization using confirmatory factor analysis. The evidence is not conclusive however, as (1) measurement scales selected for use may have "pre-disposed" the two-dimensional findings, and (2) theoretical justification for the two dimensions is weak. 31 Measurement Table l and Table 2 list the empirical studies reviewed which measure satisfaction as either an antecedent or consequent construct. Certain characteristics of the satisfaction measurement are also indicated. The variety of satisfaction measurements is discussed next, and the relationship between how satisfaction has been measured and specific research findings will be analyzed later (see section II-4.4). Table 1 indicates whether the study cited uses some form of "satisfaction/dissatisfaction" anchors for measuring satisfaction, and whether the study uses an overall and/ or attribute-specific measurement of satisfaction. Table 2 presents details of the satisfaction measurement including number of items and scale points, actual question wording, and scale anchors. Table 1 and Table 2 reveal the following: 1) The single most striking observation regarding the actual measurements of satisfaction is that no two studies measured satisfaction in an identical manner. To be sure, there are clear similarities among specific groups of studies, but there is no evidence that a standard satisfaction scale is emerging in the literature. Researchers may choose not to use previously developed scales because they believe they are examining satisfaction in a unique context or because they are testing new satisfaction measures. No matter what the reason, the consequence of using nonstandard measurement scales is that comparisons across studies and the subsequent generalizations must be approached with caution. The fundamental reason for lack of consistency in the measurement of satisfaction is the lack of agreement on its definition. This observation is not Measures of Satisfaction Anderson and Sullivan 1993 Babin, Dardin and Griffin 1993 Barbeau 1984 Bearden and Teel 1983 Bitner 1990 Bitner and Hubbert 1994 Bolfing and Woodruff 1988 Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1 987 Cardozo 1965 Churchill and Suprenant 1982 Cronin and Taylor 1992 Drbge and Halstead 1991 Fisk and Young 1985 Garland and Westbrook 1989 Halstud 1993 LaBarberra and Mazursky 1983 Mano and Oliver 1993 Oliver 1993 Oliver 1980 32 Table 1 "Sat/Dissat" On Scale NO YES NO NO NO YES NO NO NO YES YES YES NO YES YES NO NO NO By Attribute in Empirical Studies Overall <<<<<< <<< <<<<<< Tabka Oliver and DeSarbo 1988 Patterson 1993 Prakash and Lounsbury 1984 Richins and Bloch 1991 Singh 1991 Spreng and Olshavsky 1993 Swan and Martin 1981 Swan and Oliver 1991 Tse and Wilton 1988 33 1, confinued ”Sat/Dissat " On Scale YES YES YES YES YES YES NO YES By Attribute Overall <<<<<<<<< 34 .8335 - 83...... 5632955 - 8389:... .0333: . poucoucou. Lon... - 35.8. 35.8.. 38 - so... :53. .838... 29.83. . 85a 2935... .8535 29.25 - 02am 29.25.. .295» - 829.8. 3.2:: - 8238.. .3585 - 622.. SEES - 829.8. .98.. 28.25 - =3, 38.25. 32 he... - .3. 0.00m 858..» 8.. 2.2a; 20:3 .35 c. 3.53 no .8050 3.98 3: .633...an $5 3 88 2,2 so: 2:2... as? .26 8 8 a. as. . a. negative 8.28 958% use 5.; 8:58 8; _. .2388 3:8! as :0 35596 8.28 So» Sons .00.. so» In 301.. .359 .993 05 Sena .03 :0» 2:2» 26.. 58a 05 c. 33:38 383258.“. ofi .995. .3233 05 8.8 so... 5:28.... .8. use; _ :26 8 3 g 8.. . a... .25 on...» a no; ”.0330 338 05 on: 8 3.05 .50.. Sec 3.8.86 E3830 :83 3300: 50» ~09: 8.53 05 no =25 301.. 8335:. a co... Abomp 3085mm; Ea camp 32.0 cu a_wfimb (\z nectar. uo: 05203 .8383 oopxn O— E3. .8 .3; 2.3 m mom— r3500; Us 9.50m a ramp tongs: use .055 — camp 5055 e mom, .8... ac. coanm o_. vamp aaofiam m mam. acute as £38 635 p mmm— Exam was .5803 E3. ‘0 509.52 Cozumwmfiamm $0 mMEDmNOZ Dismam N 03m... 35 (\z 8.00.0000... 0000.00.00. - .8008. 0000.00.00. ........08 0.0.80 .8. .. .5002... 005.00.. 8...... 30.. .. 00000 80.9.00 .00.. _. 800.080... 00>. - .8880 00?. 800.008... 00?. - .8008... 00>. 800.0000... 030.0500. - .8008... 0000.00.00. 009000.98 020.09 00.3 000! 00 00:3 .3505. .. .03.... sabgmu b95058”: I 0028 zggmu .03§00....= - 8000.00... .0808 - 808.... 83500085 - 8.0.0... .8053... - 80.8000. .880 - 800.... 000000.00: - 000000.... .0300 . 800.0... .80 - 800. .028. 0.00 . 30.0 053. 0.00m .000. .026 00.0.6.0...2 :2. m 0.000 0. 000800.000. 00.0.03 n .0050000. 003 000....0 .0 00.000 5.2. 00.000.00.009. 80.0000 00.. 00.0.02. ... 0050000 000 8.0.03 0 .500 00800000 00 0000 000 003.00 0. E0300 02:00.. >2. n "0500000 .3026 "050000.. .3026 "800:0 "0. 000000000 :3. .0”. ”£0.30 .0. 0003.000 23— .0”. N 020030.000 a 00.00290 300000.000 0000 00030.0( 00.000. 80.80. 00.. 00.0.0.5 0 020003 0.00. 000 .00.. 0.000 02.0.0000 .N 0.00» mp ¢~\- 0— ER: 00 0000.52 nom— mma— 002.09.00.31 000. 0.0.000... 80 08.0003 000. 0.00.802. 0.... 80000 mwmp 950» us 0.0.... amp 300.0... Us on; Nam. .0300 000 0.00.0 Nam. 00000083 000 3.0055 mwmp 3025 8:84 0... 0.080.... 00.080 36 .000 00000.00... 00800.00. - .00. 00000.0 000000.00. ..00E00.00 50.. 00.3 0.03 :0» 0000.000 30.. 0000.00? 3.00 00.00.08 .00000000000: 2.0? - .b000£0_000 .00? 60000088 .0000300. .. .03th. 000 0:000 .08 0.00.... 0 000 30.. 000.00 .002 .089000 300 .00.. 00.0: 000 00:50 00 .888... 20>. - 88.00000 8? 800.09... .0030 2.0 .0... 0.. 0.00; 88.000 :0... 88.000 230.058. - ...0 00 008.000 002. L...0.000 000 00 0000.00.. 000. :0» 0.00.3 0.003 .000 .88.. 888. 230.008. .00.. 000.... 5.... 88.00000 0... 00.. 00.....0 2.0 .0 . .38. 88.000 ..0 00 002. 0.... 00.; 88.000 0.0 00.. 00.....0 2.0 =0 9.000.008. .8800... 200.205.. - 88.0000... 200.200... .0000 00...... .00.. 23.0000. - .00... 9.80.0000 8; 003 08... 0 00 .38.. .0 000.0 .00.. 000000000. :0» 0.002... S .8808 230.058. - 88.00020 .09. 00.00.00.000 .0090 .. 0.0.000 0.00.0006 .8 0 6.9000 0000 .8 ~— 0 £00. 0.00.0000... $2 0.... .20 0.... 000. 82.0 00 5.0.... $2 .....0.0 _ 00.... 0.0 . 00.0 2.8.. 00.. .00 .. .....0.....0 0...... 000 0.0. 0......0 .. .......0.0.000 2.. 000.... 8.. .8. .. .000 00.2. 0 003....00600 .02.. 20.5.3.0 .8. 0.00; . 0.000 .90 00 00 0. 8.. . 0.. 00.000 0.9.... .......0.0.0o0 2.. 00.... 88.08:... 0.000 00.0026 O— E. 0. 0.00. .00 00000. 00 .000 0.08 00050000 .N 0.00... cw-~ _. w 0000002 89 002.0 000 003m 52. 0.0.02 000 003m mam. b.9205 0:0 205m .00. 000.0 amp 0003 0:0 00.00.». .00. 230.50.. 0.... 88...... mag. 000000000 mam. 002.0 0mm. 002.0 37 new (Hunt 1977). Recently, Yi (1990) summarized the problem as follows: "For the field of C8 to develop further, a clear definition of CS is needed Before more studies are done, an effort should be made to clarify the concept of CS" (p. 74). Without a clear conceptualization, standardized operationalizations will not evolve. 2) A second striking observation from Table l and Table 2 is that numerous studies remrt incompletely, or not at all, exactly how satisfaction was measured. Some omit critical information regarding number of scale points (e.g., Oliver 1980; Bearden and Teel 1983). Some do not report the number of items (e.g., Cardozo 1965). Most, while giving specific information about the scales used, do not provide the wording questions used to elicit the scalar responses (e.g., Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987; Westbrook and Reilly 1983). Others provide only examples of specific questions asked (e.g., Bearden and Teel 1983; Swan and Oliver 1991). Finally, some provide virtually no information : for example, Fisk and Young (1985) indicate simply that "....satisfaction with choice of airline was measured." Because standards for satisfaction measurement do not exist, such omissions further cloud understanding of specific study results and complicate the process of making generalizations. 3) Given that no standard measurement exists, the task remains to document and understand the variation in measurement which does exist. One observation is that most studies utilize some overall measure of satisfaction whether alone or in combination with attribute-specific measurements. Attribute-specific measures are based on the notion that a consumer can evaluate each product/ service trait individually, is satisfied or dissatisfied with each and forms an overall satisfaction judgment in some additive fashion. 38 Reported reliabilities of such attribute-specific scales are high (e.g., Churchill and Surprenant 1982) indicating at least some support for this method. However, given that most studies use only overall measures of satisfaction, it appears the consensus is that satisfaction is a summary evaluation, and includes reactions to the gestalt of the product/ service experience. On the other hand, the prominence of overall measures may simply be due to the recognition of a practical problem: inability to specify all salient attributes would tend to reduce the validity of attribute-specific measurements. 4) Nearly half the studies reviewed used single item measures of satisfaction. Numerous studies reviewed here have utilized single item operationalizations for satisfaction as a key variable: Anderson and Sullivan (1993), Bitner (1990), Cronin and Taylor (1992), Garland and Westbrook (11989), LaBarberra and Mazursky (1983), Prakash and Lounsbury (1984), Swan and Martin (1981), Tse and Wilton (1988), and Westbrook (1980). Note that this list includes multiple studies from the lournal of Marketing and the lournal of Marketing Research. Note also that half of them have been published since 1987. Yi (1990) criticizes single-item measures on a variety of conceptual and methodological grounds, but his statement that recent studies have tended to use multi-item measures ("....in contrast to earlier studies...." ) is not supported. Studies conducted before 1988 were roughly 50% multi-item and 50% single item measures; in contrast, nearly 70% of the articles published since 1988 included only single item measures of satisfaction. Although the superiority of multiple item scales is well established, it is clear that use of single item scales remains common. 39 At the opposite extreme, four studies utilized measures constructed of ten or more items (Barbeau 1984; Churchill and Surprenant 1982; Oliver and Bearden 1983; Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987). The first three of these used so many items because their measures were, at least in part, summations of attribute-specific items. All reported at least moderately high reliabilities. 5) Scale length, or number of points per item. also exhibits wide variation. The minimum number of points appears to be four while the maximum is 11. Approximately half the studies used seven point scales. 6) The wording of satisfaction scales and guestions likewise exhibit wide variation. In fact, it is difficult to find two studies which measure satisfaction in exactly the same way. Some studies, including many which have been extremely influential in the literature, do not ever mention the word "satisfaction" in either the question wording or for the scale itself. For example, Cadotte, Woodruff and Jenkins (1987) use "feelings" as the dependent variable in their oft-cited study comparing expectations and norms as standards for disconfirmation. The 10 item "feeling" scale they employed did not use "satisfaction" in any of the items, yet they refer to satisfaction as the dependent variable in the text and title of the article. A sizable minority of studies use scales which did not include the terms "satisfied" and "dissatisfied" or any variation of those words. Four studies used some variation of the "delighted - terrible" scale. Four studies also used Likert scales. Question wording in some studies indicates that constructs other than satisfaction per se were measured. For example, Cardozo (1965) implies that satisfaction is simply the subjective evaluation of performance. Bearden and Teel (1983) and Oliver (1980) use at least one item which appears to be similar to behavioral intention: "If I had it to do over, I would feel differently about 40 using the business." Question and scale wording also reflect diversity regarding the degree to which satisfaction is thought to be primarily cognitive versus affective. Some unabashedly focus on the affective nature of satisfaction. Oliver (1980) states that "....all items were emotional in content...." (p. 463). Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins (1987) clearly favor an affect-based Operationalization by utilizing scale anchors such as "warm glow/cold feeling," "uplifted/down," "elated/tense," and "pleasant/ unpleasant." Others use both cognitive-based and affective-based items. For example, Barbeau (1984) measures response to each attribute on an "extremely well" to "extremely poorly" scale, and measures overall satisfaction on the affect-based "delighted - terrible" scale. Churchill and Surprenant (1982) explicitly acknowledge both aspects of satisfaction by measuring half their attribute- specific items as beliefs and half as affects. 7) Marticles vagwith regard to the actual "target" of satisfaction measurement. The three most common targets appear to be the product or service itself (e.g., Barbeau 1984; Churchill and Surprenant 1982; Tse and Wilton 1988), the consumption experience (e.g., Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987), and the purchase decision (e.g., Bearden and Teel 1983; Oliver 1980). Yi (1990) enumerates a more detailed list of targets. The distinctions between targets is significant. For example, one could be satisfied with one's decision to take a vacation in Florida (e.g., given the options available, access to information, etc.) but still be dissatisfied with the vacation in Florida (e.g., colder than usual), but feel satisfied with the totality of the experience (e.g., good to get away). Only one study explicitly compared satisfaction with different levels of target (Bitner and Hubbert 1993). 41 8) Notice that notwithstanding the ongoing discussion about the dimensionality of satisfaction, gtisfaction is consistently operaLtionalized as a unidimensional construct. In only a few cases were satisfaction and dissatisfaction measured separately (e.g., Westbrook and Reilly 1983), and in these cases, the scales were simply combined into a single overall measure of satisfaction. Renewed interest in the dimensionality of satisfaction is apparent, but no consensus on the issue has been reached (Babin et al 1993). Singh (1991) implies a two-dimensional conceptualization given his measure of satisfaction which ranges from "not satisfied at all" to "completely satisfied." Likewise, Richins and Bloch (1991) and Westbrook (1980) imply two dimensional conceptualizations with their numerical scales which range from 0% to 100%, where 096 is labeled "not at all satisfied" and 100% is labeled "completely satisfied." These scales indicate that the opposite of satisfaction is absence of satisfaction rather than dissatisfaction. However, in two of these studies (Singh 1991; Westbrook 1980), this is the only item used to measure satisfaction. The degree to which such measures, as opposed to the more traditional bipolar scales, alter the revealed relationships between satisfaction and its antecedents is unclear. The important observation at this point is that most researchers actually measure satisfaction as if it were unidimensional. Inconsistent operationalizations of the satisfaction construct mirror the inconsistent conceptualizations of satisfaction. Numerous calls have been made for development of agreed upon operationalizations of satisfaction, but little progress has been made on this problem. Until standard measures of satisfaction are widely implemented and shown to have reliability and validity across a range of contexts, the question "what exactly is being measured 42 here?" will remain. Hunt (1977) states that the study of customer satisfaction is "...much more advanced in measurement and methodology than...in conceptual development" (p. 16). While much progress has been made since 1977, the statement is still true. In summary, satisfaction 0 is generally measured as a unidimensional construct, 0 often measured using a single item, 0 has a variety of "targets," 0 most often uses seven point scales, 0 exhibits wide variation in scale wording, but usually includes the word "satisfaction" or a variation of that word. In this dissertation, the few conventions regarding satisfaction measurement which do exist are followed. Specifically, satisfaction is conceptualized as unidimensional, measured using a single 7-point item, and is anchored by "extremely satisfied" and "extremely dissatisfied." In addition, two levels of targets of satisfaction are used: satisfaction with a specific target and overall satisfaction. II-3. l . Expectation Expectation is the subjective belief that an event or some attribute of an event will occur, or that a product possesses some attribute, or that some product will perform in a certain manner. Expectation can be measured at the attribute and/ or overall level. It can be measured either with regard to relevant attribute characteristics (e.g., "hot/cold," "dull/bright," etc.) or as an evaluation of the attribute characteristics (e.g., "excellent/poor"). Olson and 43 Dover (1979), in an effort to clarify the exact nature of expectations, demonstrated that expectations may be conceptualized as product-specific beliefs. Notions of expectation can be complex. Miller (1977) identifies four types of expectations: the ideal, the expected, the tolerable, and the deserved. Conceptually, a good case could be made for using any of the four, and the appropriate choice may vary by situation. Although most research examined here uses "predictive expectations," the alternatives have not been shown to be inappropriate. Czepiel and Rosenberg (1977) propose an algebraic version of the above. They specify three types of expectation: 1) what the subject would like to occur, 2) what the subject thinks Mid. occur, and 3) what the subject thinks w_i11 occur. They suggest that the numerical difference between one of these expectations and what actually occurs should be summed on an attribute by attribute basis to calculate customer satisfaction. Several of the studies examined used variants of this approach. Swan (1981) contends that these variations of expectations are actually points along an "expectation continuum." Consumers have a "modal expectation level" that incorporates the probability of occurrence and the evaluation of the probable occurrence. Thus, for example, consumers take into account all the different types proposed by Miller (1977) and arrive at a realistic modal expectation for a given situation. Simply asking the consumer what he or she expects to occur or what quality is expected yields an overall expectation rating. Though other researchers do not refer to the "modal expectation level," many use this formulation. 44 Expectations have also been linked to attitudes. For example, Oliver and Linda (1981) state: "Perhaps the most general workable definition is that of Katona ( 1964) who referred to expectations as a 'subclass of attitudes that point to the future (p. 34).' As such, they may be seen as prediction of affect" (p. 88). Expectations is one of the earliest and perhaps most consistently studied constructs in the satisfaction formation literature. It was used as an independent variable in early studies of perceived performance. (e.g., Cardozo 1965; Olshavsky and Miller 1972) and in nearly every study of antecedents of satisfaction. Further, it is the construct most closely connected to the theoretical roots of the satisfaction literature. In the service satisfaction literature, measurements labeled "expectations" usually refer to "desires" (e.g., desired level of service). In order to avoid confusion, this distinction will be clarified as necessary. Table 3 lists the studies which utilize expectations in a satisfaction formation model. It indicates whether expectations are measured and/ or manipulated experimentally, and whether measurement occurred before or after "performance." Table 4 indicates whether expectations are measured by overall versus attribute-specific items, the number of items and scale points used, question wording and scale anchors. The following are observations regarding these tables. (1) Although most of the studies reviewed included expectations as a potentiaLantecedent varia_bl_e, over one-third did not (see Table 3). Two additional studies, Cardozo (1965) and Olshavsky and Miller (1972), manipulated expectations in a laboratory setting, but did not measure them. Tse and Wilton 45 Table 3 Measures of Expectations Not Manipu- Before After Measured Measured lated Performance Performance Anderson and Sullivan 1993 J J Babin, Darden and Griffin 1993 J Barbeau 1984 J \/ Bearden and Teel 1983 J J Bitner 1990 J Bolfing and Wooduff 1988 J J Cadotte, Wooduff. and Jenkins 1987 J J Cardozo 1965 \/ \/ \/ Churchill and Surprenant 1982 J J J Cronin and Taylor 1992 J J Drbge and Halstead 1991 J J Halstead 1993 J J Mano and Oliver 1993 J Oliver 1993 \/ Oliver and Bearden 1983 J J Oliver and Desarbo 1988 J J Oliver and Linda 1981 J J Olshavsky and Miller 1972 J Patterson 1993 J J Parasuraman, Zeithaml and Berry 1988 J Prakash and Lounsbury 1984 J J Richins and Blodi 1991 J Sindr 1991 \/ \/ Spreng and Olshavsky 1993 J J Swan and Martin 1981 Swan and Oliver 1991 Swan and Trawick 1981 Tse and Wilton 1988 Westbrook 1980 Westbrook 1981 Westbrook and Newman 1978 Westbrook and Reilly 1983 46 Table 3, continued Not Manipu- Before After Measured Measured Iated Performance Performance v J J v \/ v v J J v v v v 47 .3: use; 23:3? - .33; 232:8. 8:522: 58» 5:32.... doc-Lacuna "835: 3 ".326 ”83.2. 2. ..Eo=ouxo.. . .uoou be) 3:. .5535“. 03:28» and» n 8.3. .9. 28.88 :8 .3. 3.8 .. 8.... .9. 528:882 .0328 859... 3 £3... .figxfia. .8828? t8€§£9959 98:83... 859.... .838 .o 38.. .93.. 32.. "8.3.5.. 9.5.3.... 2. .85... 3 23:10 $98.2 8.8» 583 5.3 85:8.6 322.... so... it. 8 3.2 Log 5.! 2538.3. 835 .06 2.8 0828.5 a 050% .35» __a 3 Se. - .323 =3 2.? seasons-E .0 88:23.. .828 .o no.9. .E... .o c3832. .38.: .o 9.3... .2855. - .295. hoe-8.. .383 883288... .238 2.8.55. - .__o3 22.2.? 3335: o to”. :53: I :30? (\2 Room .3280 e m > k as v > > m m > > n k > k m > s o > o P P > £3. .2. .53. so =Eo>o 3.5.3: 5.. 38m .35.: an mcozmuoooxm Co $5302 050on v «33 32 Been: a... «2.5 mom. «5:053 use 55.550 mum— 809.8 8.: 8:2... 2. £683 .588 8a, .3683 E. 8.28 mmm— 30h use canteen Vow _. :38 mmmp Caz-3m us cocoa-.3 48 A90 .38 .8? Enema... iota .o. 33> uooa .823 uooo "0.5.9.. 35953 coon .o. .66. A6: 51.9 ace... .32 .o 3.5.. do: .828 woo. a. s... :2. 2.; 8:8 68. .o 33 "83.9.. «8353 5:838»... poo. .o. .6... .6523. «.9228... 0.2.2.8 8o .3 5.2.2. 8 2s... a: .82.. a 39.. 3.2 k 2: > $2 .3833 2.. .39.... r328. 3. 3.! .38 3 8 .88.. 2.. 88.x. _ 628.28 «8.5 ..<. .335. .858... 29.2%. - .85. 282.». .326 a... 8.3.3. o. .o. 3.2 m 2 > > 82 :88... £88.? 83....- one}: ”329.8 9.5.. :3 58...... 83.2.. 23.8. 588 9.5.. so: > > 2.: 3...: 2a 2.225 mwmp coin use .025 $3.38»? .. . .ulfiuu. €9.38... - .288... ...&1.5. - $9.2. ".335 .335». 53 8 2825.32.39... 3.953202%... $2.38»... to? . .33...» 22,. .6... 3.3.8 so... 88...... 8 E8882 no.3. . 2 > > 8.: an... E. .36 .955 38.. 8m 28.88 53.. 2...: > 8.... 8.88 .8. .56 .3... - .uoou. ”8.09:0 03.89. gone .0: 2808.8 c.5515 g .528. . .855 8. c982 8393 3 9.3.88. 288.58 .38 A v. > > 82 528.. B. .55 0.3m scan-ad Sea. .2. IE3. no .335 32...»: .8. 38m .35... .6 33528 JV 0.2.... t'I-Flcfithlni “V Chafillhl 49 .835. . .05.. 28.0.88. .....on 8 a. 388.8 so» 8... on ....s .8 so» too. 05 up... no» 8a 0.8 26.... 63:3. .26. do... $3.583»... to? . ....omao... 28.288. ......3 :o» 3:02. .3 o. u. 6098 so» o.... «a... o. woo. 2: .... 9.0.8838 “8.3.022 25.8. .96. ...... do... .. 5.8388 38.8.... . 228%.... ......s 8.8.85.5. ......26 ......3... 5.8.... 35.82.. ......E ..3. 5885552.. ......322... .3... 8 ...... ....ot8 ...... .. .8...» 5.8... .o 88.5.98... 3308303833.. L032. 2.9.0.. £55.05“. 035.com «6:8... .0 Eco... .0982... "83953 ......a... €31.33... .....Eo . 33.3.. 52.35.... . angina .02. .0350... ..o.oo.. ..flofitafi. ....Eiu. 833.5% m ......83 ...-.2... 82026 .....a 3.5.. I: c. 3.23 89.. 3.... 655.. 05 .... so» 8 8.23 .3qu 02a ...... 8039:. .30» 028.... £038.. So» .0 23 8.5 8 :38 83.5059 8.8.... .82.... 8 .3 8628...... ......32. 2.... o... .2. .. a. as... .29....3 be... - .29... be... _ .28.. o... o. ......38. 2.. 8:8... .5.A 8.82. 0.08 .3330 vouczcou .V 0.9.... me— xgiflh Ba :95 8a.. £95! I3 anm 8.: b.9230 u... 22%.. 8.... .2... 50 ..0.5.. .60). - .00.. .005 a. .voom b0? . .30.. b0... .uoou .00... - Loon b0). boom .00? - ..ooo b0? 0.08 ..Eonfluoaxo 0005 .o .25... ...... ...... garage... 368.... 5. 883:... I . ..coalE.....80.u. 00.3000... 5.. ..338935. a. .833 .052 ....u. on too. .0 ..000 0.5.. no» 9.5.62.0 05.00.83 .000 8 509.0 332.. o». «05 09.858395. "oglEotoa “.300an 503.8... 05 act-5.5.. ... >05... .56 So» .o on» 0882.. :2. .. 0.88.... .3280... 3 use... .2. oflgota...u 6389a 038...... .205. 28.. 0550...... 0 ... 000 8 0.... 2.63 no» 0835? .o 802.9..8 .... .58.. 8... =5 .23.. a .o 8:052... 081.85.... 68...... .8... m R cot-0:0 E00. .0: 083. .o .8: 0.00m .0952 coactcoo ... 030... \( ..805 \1. 8.3.32 an 8.: .....s. .8. .8380... cam— x8530; mom— can—ts .80 3h 51 (1988) and Churchill and Surprenant (1982) manipulated and measured expectations. (2) Though most studies measured expectations prior to product/ service exposure, five did not. "Predictive expectations" measured following the experience is really a measure of remembered predictive expectations, subject to modification due to the passage of time, the known performance, the subjects' reaction to the performance, and other potentially confounding factors. Thus, it is generally considered to be an inferior measure of predictive expectations. All five studies which used post-performance measures of "predictive expectations" were field studies designed to avoid the artificial environment of a laboratory setting. Some of the problems involved in using ex m measures of expectations are discussed in Drége and Halstead (1991), Halstead (1993), and Yi (1990). (3) Table 4 provides the details of how expectations were measured for each of the studies reviewed. Note that all but three studies measured attribute- specific expectation or attribute-specific and overall expectations. Two of the three studies which did not measure attribute-specific expectations, Cardozo (1965) and Oliver and DeSarbo (1988) both were laboratory studies and both manipulated expectations regarding performance. However, even in these cases, subjects were provided with a few attribute-specific cues, so it could be argued that all studies but one either manipulated or measured at least some attribute-specific expectations. (4) Table 4 also indicates wide variation in the number of items used to ogrationalize expectations. At one extreme is the study by Tse and Wilton (1988) which used 27 items; at the other extreme are studies by Swan and 52 Trawick (1981) - which appears to use a single item scale created by multiplying an expectation times the probability of its occurrence - and Anderson and Sullivan (1993). (S) The number of scale points per item likewise exhibits some variation ranging from four points to ten points, with seven points also representing the mode. (6) Note that Westbrook and Reilly (1983) allowed subjects to choose those characteristics about which they recalled expectations in an open-ended format. Thus, the number of items on which expectations were measured varied from subject to subject. (This measurement technique may have contributed to the failure to develop a significant overall model.) (7) Variation is most evident in the specifics of question and scale wording. Note first of all that actual questions are rarely provided, though attributes measured are usually specified. Likewise, scale anchors are often omitted though readers are told that "semantic differential" (or "bi-polar") scales were used. (8) On close examination of exactly what was measured, it is questionable whether one of the studies which claims to measure expectations actually does (Westbrook 1980). In reality, he measures performance relative to expectations, or disconfirmation. It should be noted that two additional studies claim to measure expectations but do not and thus are not included here. Parasuraman, Zeithaml and Berry (1988) and Cronin and Taylor (1992) actually measure "desires," not expectations. Both studies use the SERVQUAL scale which consistently used the word "should" in all items (i.e., "Please show the extent to which you think institutions offering _.__ services should possess the 53 features described"). This could be interpreted as normative or idealized expectations, but they clearly are not expectations in a predictive sense. (9) On close examination, there are three kinds of "targets" of expectations, i.e., expectations are measured with regard to three subtly different aspects of product/ service performance. First, expectations are measured with regard to perceptions of objective performance. Most of the studies using semantic differential (or bipolar) scales fall into this category. For example, Cadotte, Woodruff and Jenkins (1987) measure "speed of service" on a "fast - slow" continuum. Second, expectations are measured with regard to overtly subjective evaflltions of performance. Scales such as Oliver's (1980) "good - ba " scale or the Tse and Wilton (1988) "very poor - very good" scale fall into this category. For these scales, the anchors themselves are evaluative. Third, expectations are measured with regard to the level of satisfaction expected from the product/ service performance. In other words, respondents are asked their expected reaction to an expected level of an attribute. See for example the question wording used by Oliver and Linda (1981) as indicated on Table 4. 10) Finally, a couple of studies use a combination of types of ta_rge_t. Churchill and Surprenant (1982) use evaluation of performance as an overall expectation measure, while Swan and Martin (1981) use anticipated level of satisfaction as an overall expectation measure. It seems likely that as expectation measures move farther away from objective performance as a target, individual responses become less and less comparable across respondents. For example, one person may expect "poor service promptness" and another may expect "good service promptness," and both may expect to be served in 15 minutes. The problem is exacerbated when expectations are compared with performance. For example, assume both 54 people were actually served in 20 minutes. The first person may be pleasantly surprised if he dislikes feeling rushed. The second may be unhappy if he dislikes waiting. Not only are expectations and performance confounded, expectations and desires are also confounded in such scales. It may be true that expected evaluations of and expected satisfaction with performance is a superior predictor of satisfaction because predictive expectations and expected responses are combined in these two measures. Nevertheless, expectation of objective performance is closer to the original conceptualization of expectations as a cognition-based construct. Yet even commonly used measures of expectations regarding objective performance are flawed. For example, using "fast" and "slow" to anchor expected service promptness measures may be more "objective" than using "very good" and "very poor." However, even the former set of anchors is subject to most of the same issues regarding individual interpretation. In addition, it is difficult to envision a truly objective expectations measure for some attributes such as "food quality" in Cadotte, Woodruff and Jenkins (1987). In summ expectation appears as a construct in about two-thirds of the studies reviewed. Most studies used predictive expectation measures obtained prior to performance, though several actually measured expectations following performance. There is wide variation in question wording, the number of measurement items and points per scale item. Expectations have been measured with regard to (1) objective performance, (2) evaluation of performance, and (3) level of satisfaction. In short, operationalization of expectations has suffered from three inconsistencies. mat, it has suffered from the problem of which attributes to include. Even when attributes have been identified by extensive pretesting, 55 there is no guarantee that salient attributes are not omitted. When subjects are allowed to state which attributes are salient to them personally, variation between subjects may contribute to problems in fitting the model (e.g., Westbrook and Reilly, 1983). Second, operationalization of expectations has also suffered from the variety of expectations targets, i.e., expectations regarding the product service performance versus expectations regarding the level of satisfaction likely to result from the product/ service performance. Further, within the realm of expectations regarding performance, expectations may be measured with regard to the performance itself or with regard to subjective evaluations of performance. 111i_r_d_, operationalization of expectation has suffered from lack of comparability of expectations across subjects, or from one construct to another within a single study. In this thesis all three of the problems apparent in the current literature will be addressed. First, the problem of relevant attributes is solved by asking subjects specifically what proportion of the popular vote they expect each candidate to receive. In other words, the target event is so specific that it is defined as possessing a single attribute. Expectations regarding this single attribute can be measured exactly. Similarly, the target also possesses an unambiguous measure of objective performance, and thus the expectation measure is of predictive expectations. Finally, the measure is on the same scale as two other relevant constructs: desires and actual performance. Therefore, more than in any other study published to date, responses across respondents will be comparable. 56 II-3.2. Desires "Desires" is a general term indicating the direction and strength of what a person wants to receive from a product or service. Although it seems logical that "desires" would be modeled as an antecedent of satisfaction, especially given early definitions of marketing, "desires" has only recently become the focus of serious attention in the satisfaction literature (with one early exception: Barbeau 1984). In at least three ways, however, "desires" has indirectly entered the satisfaction literature. First, desires appears to have explicitly entered the satisfaction literature as a disconfirmation standard rather than as an independent construct. Westbrook and Reilly (1983) introduced the concept of "value- percept disparity" in a study which was marked by both design and measurement problems. Value-percept disparity was operationalized as "....the extent to which the respondents' automobile provided the features and performance characteristics needed or desired" (p. 258). As such, it may be thought of as a kind of "desires disconfirmation"; desires were not measured separately (though expectations were). Second, Sirgy (1984) manipulated desires in an experiment by asking respondents to imagine an "ideal" level of an attribute. However, he did not measure the effects of the manipulation on satisfaction. Third, desires have been introduced to the satisfaction literature through operationalizations of expectations. When respondents are asked to state expectations on an evaluative scale (e.g., "very poor" -- "very good"), the implication is that expectations occur relative to some "norm" or "ideal," which appears to be closely related to a "desired" level. For example, Tse and Wilton (1988) conceptualized "ideal expectations" as the "anticipated performance of a 57 player that 'has exactly the combination of attribute you would like to see....'" (p. 206). Likewise, as we illustrated in the previous section, Oliver (1980) operationalized expectations as the sum of the cross products of attribute specific beliefs (degree to which product possesses an attribute) and evaluation of the attribute (degree to which attribute is good/ bad). The evaluation component reflects respondent desires relative to that attribute (Spreng and Dixon 1992). Woodruff, Cadotte, and Jenkins (1983) suggest a move away from pure expectations to an antecedent which is more desires-based: desires as constrained by realistic expectations. In reporting the results of an empirical test of their ideas, Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins (1987) summarize their position as follows: "....consumers are likely to rely on standards that reflect the performance a consumer believes a focal brand should provide to meet needs/wants....These norms have two important characteristics: (1) they reflect desired performance in meeting needs/wants and (2) they are constrained by the performance consumers believe is possible..." (p. 306). Since desires have appeared explicitly in so few studies, its specific operationalizations will not be presented in a separate table, but will be presented in the discussion which follows. In 1984, Barbeau published a study which explicitly compared the effects of expectations and desires on satisfaction. Both direct effects on satisfaction and indirect effects (via the use of each as disconfirmation standards) were measured. Despite the promising results when desires was used as a standard for disconfirmation, desires was not included in a product-oriented model again until 1990, when Spreng uses desires as the centerpiece of his satisfaction model. Spreng and Olshavsky (1993) measure both "desires" and "desires congruency" in an experiment 58 involving subjects' responses to a new camera. Desires is operationalized using both attribute and overall measures. The question is worded: "Given your individual photographic needs and desires, what would be the level of __ you desire?" "Clarity," "sharpness," "color," and "overall picture quality" are the four items for which the question is asked. In the service satisfaction literature, the construct labeled "expectation" usually is measured as desires. In fact, Parasuraman, Zeithaml, and Berry (1988) state " in the service quality literature, expectations are viewed as desires or wants of consumers, i.e., what they feel a service provider gro_ulg_ offer rather than M offer" (p. 17). There has been some discussion about whether desires is best conceptualized as lying on a "more is better" continuum versus an "ideal point" continuum (e.g., Spreng 1992). There are some attributes for which "more is better," such as "quality" or "value." Other attributes, such as "warmth" have an ideal desired point because it is logical for something to possess either too much or too little warmth. Recently, Westbrook (1987) and Westbrook and Oliver (1991) have investigated the dimensionality of affective responses to performance. Yet neither of these studies looked at the pre- performance construct of desires. Problems involved with measuring desires on an evaluative scale are evident. For example, Barbeau (1984) used scale anchors "extremely well" and "extremely poorly" to measure desired level of attributes. If one attribute is of the "more is better" variety (e.g., in that study, "development of marketing skills"), why would someone desire "extremely poor" performance? Why would someone desire any performance other than that which is "extremely well?" If another attribute in the same study is of the "ideal point" variety, 59 (e.g., in Barbeau's study, "degree of challenge"), does a high rating indicate a high degree of challenge or a level of challenge identical to the subject's ideal level of challenge? Thus, when "desires" scales are evaluative, is difficult to interpret responses logically. Also, it seems that there would be minimal variance in evaluative desires as everyone would want attributes at me_ir ideal level or at the maximum level of a "more is better" attribute. Further, it appears highly questionable to create a single desires indicator by summing across a mixture of "more is better" and "ideal point" measures. One additional issue is the degree to which respondents take other attributes into account when rating their desires. For example, an individual may desire a car which is "highly luxurious" but may temper that desire with the knowledge that they have $10,000 to spend on the car. Thus, the context in which desires are measured is critical for understanding results. In this dissertation these problems with desires measurement will be minimized. Respondents will be able to specify a level of desire on a non- evaluative, unambiguous scale whether they personally perceive desires in this context to be of the "more is better" or "ideal point" variety. Desire is operationalized as the degree to which a respondent wishes to distribute choice points to one alternative relative to two other mutually exclusive choices. Respondents can allocate all 100 points to their preferred alternative ("more is better") or give the preferred choice some specific number of points less than 100 ("ideal point"). In other words, desire is measured with regard to a total "package" of attributes relative to other "packages" of attributes rather than to a single attribute. An additional benefit of this operationalization of desire is that levels of desire can be directly compared with other relevant constructs (e.g., expectations) and across individuals. 60 II-3.3. Attitudes Attitude has been used as both an antecedent and consequent construct in satisfaction formation models. Attitude is generally considered to be an ongoing or persistent affective orientation to a particular "attitude object," or a subjective overall evaluation of an object. The most widely used attitude model is the Fishbein model (Fishbein and Ajzen 1975). The model defines attitude as the sum of the cross products of the strength of belief that an object possesses an attribute and the evaluation of the attribute, across all salient attributes. In other words, attitudes possess a cognitive component (very similar to long-term expectations; see Katona 1964) and an affective component. Only three studies have utilized attitude as an antecedent variable in satisfaction formation models, so a table providing operationalization details will not be presented. (In addition, all three studies used similar attitude measures.) In Oliver (1980), Oliver and Bearden (1983), and Oliver and Bearden (1985), attitudes are measured using 9-item semantic differential scales. In Oliver (1980), attitudes about receiving flu inoculations are measured, while in the latter two studies, attitudes toward diet pills are measured. Exact operationalizations of attitudes in these two studies are not presented. Theoretical justification for including attitude as an antecedent in satisfaction formation processes is that if attitude is a persistent orientation to an object, attitude may impact satisfaction via its effect on perception of performance and disconfirmation (Oliver and Bearden 1983). In addition, Yi (1990) indicates that attitudes are hypothesized to affect expectations and 61 perceived performance judgments; this is thought to be especially true among low involvement consumer, because low involvement consumers are thought to be less attentive to actual performance and thus rely more on pre performance factors in forming satisfaction. In this dissertation, a multi-attribute conception of attitude is used. It is operationalized using four attributes and is constructed using a modified version of the Fishbein model, with attribute "importance" rather than attribute "evaluation" as the factor with which belief is multiplied (Fishbein 1967) II-3.4. Perceived performance Churchill and Surprenant (1982) were the first to suggest that perceived performance affects satisfaction. They hypothesize the influence to be both direct and indirect (through disconfirmation). Tse and Wilton (1988) extend the theoretical justification for including perceived performance in the model. They suggest that sometimes consumers have a "learning motive" for consumption, i.e., consumers want to learn about a new product; consumers may thus be satisfied with the product "regardless of the levels of pre- experience comparison standard and disconfirmation" (p. 205). In addition, they hypothesize that the consumption experience M, especially if it is extremely positive or negative, will affect post-consumption evaluation in accord with cognitive dissonance theory, and will thus have a direct effect on satisfaction. In some previous studies, constructs which are labeled as "product performance" actually are operationalized in a manner very similar to disconfirmation. For example, Olshavsky and Miller (1972) asked subjects to 62 rate overall and attribute specific tape recorder performance relative to ".... an ideal or perfect recorder" (p. 20). By providing subjects with a comparison standard, the construct "performance" at best is confounded; at worst, it may be considered to be a measure of disconfirmation. Table 5 lists the studies which utilize performance in a satisfaction formation model. It indicates whether performance is measured and/or manipulated experimentally, whether performance is measured by overall versus attribute-specific items, the number of items and scale points used, question wording and scale anchors. Table 5 indicates the following: 1) Although the studies presented in Table 5 all claim to measure performance, in at least two of the casesI the operationalizations of perceived performance appears to be confounded. These studies, and the potential confound in each, are: a) Fisk and Young (1985) explicitly measured performance relative to a standard ("waiting time" relative to what was "expected" and "fare paid" relative to a "friend's"), and therefore it appears to be more like a disconfirmation measure. b) Olshavsky and Miller (1972) explicitly measured performance relative to a standard ("....compared to an ideal or perfect recorder...."), and therefore it appears to be more like a disconfirmation measure. 2) Cronin and Taylor (1992) and Parasuraman, Zeithaml, and Berry (1988) both measured performance using the SERVQUAL scale. The Question wording is somewhat confusing in that subjects are first told that it's their "feelings" which are of interest (an affective cue), and then they are asked to rate how strongly they agree or disagree that a provider possessed or exhibited a specific attribute (a cognitive task). 63 80:. .mun 2 .o». 8.5 998.5 .m> .85. 33.3952 89: ...caoc N. 8 .3556 o. 2:; 0:36; 85098 .m> .25» 953;. 35:95: > > 33 33> pen in. was. .2333 .... .8 8x2 ..Eoesau 2: 3 39:83 838. 9: 8: ~>x 26:3 :0» 523 2 $068 05 :65 885 48363 er Son- moc=02 50» .85» zucozm. - .8536 20:87.. 3 828 85888» 3 you. 3.26:8 2.... u mm > > mm? .033. new 5:20 fission. - 29:8. m. :5 o5 .0 £26 ...BoS. 3.208 1888.552: :93 ..cfi .58 Hosanna B x cm; > > > > 32 22293 2.. ...;236 2.. es 8. a S ta: _ _ > > 89 38.6 .835 098.an __o 5:26. $23395. 3695520. Louooxsofimoes. .88....83 85%.? 8.8... 585 .858 .0 39%. 19.3.. 82. 68352 m o > x. > 32 255.. u... £3803 6:88 assets. 22%.: I 3.28% so: toss 585... .3 S .8. - .35... :9; be? ..85 5? £585? E96 .3 «co 5 a > > > 32 5.325 95 95.8 .98.... €585. - ..Es $585. $835.." w to“. k m > > 32 38.8 > 89 5:5 2.. 828 533 $3293. - Eng-.5. .5526 520 62k. 883. .52. - .30.. .83 8% .Eaaa 8!. o. N > > 82 52:3 v:- 8885. Snow 8.50:0 ES. .2. «£8. .0 __20>o 3:232 noun. v2.5.0! team-ox 3.. 2.8 3.52 .6 52:0: 32 oocwfiuotom no «2332 0:3on m Ban... 64 .333 “5.85. .535 23%. :23? 2.8.3 F - .933 88 .225? 128. ..mflceofi. .5220. «835: m .83 88 ”828. 8:55: .33 .2 :93 38 582, 2.2. 6810 3:26 Jon 828 Bo. .u. 9:. so» is 258 68a .0 an: ”320:. 9:558 5:836? 38 .2 :98 23:28.6 ”5588 .335“. :08 co negated 93.5 a :6: 09.2 .8586 zocotm. - .35. bucobm. .526 P pco «93.53 9 ..ucocasfi 2: B vacuums 238. as 8: 69 31.8 3» 62; 2 “Sea «5 32m 88: .9388 S Sons 35.00.. 50» .85u 29.8%. - .8585 29.9%. 8 822 3:068.“ ..o “8 3.32.0. on». nzofio .5882 SEE: .235 8.. £8: .85, .8 5:8: .6556 «o .33. 2( 9. 035.28.. ”952 in :35: ..o)! 3.0: 059.308 60:58 .Qnfimon ~20! - 03.38 «mom. -2“. Eat Eaton...— .omconm2 A8252. $3353 223.288 98. 6m 89 “5:28 532 :9: G18... cat-“...“: 2. 3:82 225. 2. 2.8 u... no.8» 505.9... $3203 8:353 n_o_ucocotfi 332.com oucweuoton “cc .5080ng "2 con-3.90 “9:08.. 8.2.8 .....uaona 0.253 .02 .... .58. «05.00.. 03>...» 9.3 E00303 8.28 .ucoEEoSco pole 30: ..-... Son. 8293 .03 _. Evan .ucoEcoutEo .aufixza 603.05 8§tuu< 1.8. 8.880 poaczcou .m 03m... n h\—_. k v 53. .8 2.8. .0 .356 83.32 2.. 1.3. 33:52 \( >0 93-. 923-0: 023-0: -323! \v no.2 b.9220 8. 88% v8. 5.328.. Ea 53.2.. mam — c8353. 39 Pom new _EE._oN .caecam8& ~02 wk: .55: u... b.9656 mmmp 096060 new 52.0 82 82.0 on. can: 002 302933 pco ucatno 65 ..82 _ .2; 2.8.8 832.. - .muooc an. c2.» 80. .2 332a. Loon. - 22.85. .8386 39.25 - 85a .2395. 3:89. .8 Room £3?de EwUxma-w:4<>. fluz<2¢0umwa “.0 mung! 95a ...02 HPPOZ .wuooc 805 SE 0.5023... 29.53 9 0803 3!. co...» 9... 6.50833. :- c. 38: .392 38.33 m ~ \r oocoEBton uooo .m> oucactotoa .00.... 6323.5: \r > ....63 too. 05 20305 39A 26.. m: =8 3.8.... n .. \z ...: 3288 5.56.8 6:. 5.3 05.9% .... c. Sn 558.8 .2. 5.3 8.38 .... 3208. . 62.8.8 5.; 3.38 s. c. 5.. . 6.58.8 5.; 8.38 s. k 8 > .553..sz ..Ego..... ...226 .05.? .88.... 35.22.. .82.. =2... .BBocaciis. bias? .3... 2 :2. L525... 3.... .05.?» 3:3... .8 $29.68.... .motoamouuohcozqo. 1.038 8.05. Lots... .o 58... 39.8.... 63352 u m. > > 8.30:0 £3. .2. 2:3. .3 .....o>o 3.5.52 3.. 0.3m .363... Am non—5:00 .m 035... $30. 02:30: 3.330: LEE-a no: 32 »...3. .8. .6988; comp 202.3 0:. 8* —om_. x239; Uca :95 amp .025 0:9 :95 amp Eta! Dan cgm 66 3) In five of the studies, performance is manipulated; in two of these cases, perceived performance is not measured, so actual performance becomes the relevant independent variable. Performance and expectation are the two most commonly-manipulated variables in satisfaction formation research because they can be consistently and easily controlled. The motivation for manipulating performance is not only to manipulate perceived performance, but also to manipulate disconfirmation. Disconfirmation has been the focus of so much attention in satisfaction research and there is no readily apparent way to manipulate disconfirmation directly. 4) The mgioritv of studies mea_suredjattribute-specific performance or both attribute—specific and overall performance. Only three studies measured overall performance alone, and these were studies involving products/ services that are simple to evaluate (e.g., pen, ROI, etc.) 5) Except for the three studies which use only an overall measure, perceived performance is measured using 7-point scafis (range is from 5- points to 8-points). Number of items used ranged from 4 to 28 items. In this dissertation perceived performance is measured in one model and not measured in the other. In the model which includes perceived performance, it is measured conventionally, that is, using 7-point scales and multiple attributes. In the other model, perceived performance is not measured because actual performance (i.e., the election outcome) is so clear, and so widely known and accepted, that an objective measure of perceived performance is considered unnecessary. 67 II-3.S. Disconfirmation Disconfirmation is a person's evaluation of product or service performance relative to some standard. Performance above the standard is traditionally referred to as "positive disconfirmation," performance below the standard is referred to as "negative disconfirmation," and performance at the standard is referred to as "confirmation." Disconfirmation has been operationalized in a wide variety of ways. Table 6 and Table 7 list all the empirical studies reviewed which utilized disconfirmation, and certain relevant characteristics of how it was operationalized. All operationalizations can be categorized along two dimensions: 1) subjective versus derived (computational) measures, and 2) standard which is being disconfirmed. The resulting matrix and the classification of studies utilizing disconfirmation as an antecedent construct is shown in Table 8. The first dimension, subjective versus derived measures. refers to a critical conceptual difference in how disconfirmation is ogrationalized. Subjective disconfirmation refers to the direct measurement of a person's evaluation of disconfirmation. Such measures are taken following the subject's experience of the product or service. Typically, the subject would be asked to rate whether the performance was "better than expected" or "worse than expected" on some scale. Reporting overall disconfirmation in this manner allows the subject to consider the entire experience relative to expectations or whatever standard is used. Derived measures of disconfirmation are indirect measures in that the subject is not directly asked the degree to which performance meets the stan- dard (e. g., expectations). Instead, measures of the standard are collected before Measures of Disconfirmation Am and Suan 1993 Babin, Darden and Griffin 1993 Barbeau 1984 Bearden and Tool 1983 Bitner 1990 Boiling and Woodruff 1988 Brown and Swartz 1989 Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987 Churchill and Suprenant 1982 Cronin and Taylor 1992 Drape and Halstead 1991 Oliver 1980 Oliver 1993 Oliver and Bearden 1983 Oliver and Desarbo 1988 Oliver and Swan 1989 Olshavsky and Miller 1972 Parasuraman, Zeithaml, and Barry 1988 Patterson 1993 Prakash and Lounsbury 1984 Richins and Bloch 1991 Spreng and Olshavsky 1993 Swan and Martin 1985 Tse and Wilton i988 Westbrook 1980 Westbrook and Reilly 1978 Derived or By Subjective Attribute subjective subjective derived V subjective 7 subjective derived V subjective subjective V NOT MEASURED subjective V subjective subjective subjective derived V (manipulated) subjective 7 subjective V derived V derived V derived V subjective subjective V derived V subjective subjective V subjective V 68 Table 6 Overall in Empirical Studies .. ________ Standard Disconfirmad---_....-_-. Product Best Predictive Past type brand Expectation Desire Experience Ideal Norm Norm V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V V 4 V" V V V " predictive and equitable upectations (2 treasures) Anderson and Sullivan 1993 Babin. Darden and Griffin 1993 Barbeau 1984 BeardenandTeel 1983 Bitner1990 Bolfing and Woodruff 1988 BrovvnandSwartz 1989 Cadotte, Woodmfr, and Jenkins 1987 Cardozo 1965 Churchill and Surprenant 1982 Cronin and Taylor 1992 Drbpemdllalstead 1991 Oliver 1980 Oliver 1993 Number Scale Pts. of Items per Item 1 65 “42 69 Table 7 Specific Measures of Disconfirmation 10 7 Question N/A e.g., 'The product materials improved my score by about as much as I expected it to.“ (perfomance minus standard) for 8 attributes assumed constant; verified. but scales not provided Askedoncel‘oreachstandard. (performance minus expectation) for each ttribute Asked once for each standard. Assumed to be manipulate: not measured. wmiimmmmmizmm rezplayermdonceforeverall e.g.rorcost: E.p. for overall: “My expectation regarding the perform or the product was.-.“ Asked regarding cupet (woe. durfiility, stain resistance) and service (wermty. retailer service) Asked of innoculation recipients: Problems encountered Benefitsmceived Aslned of non-recipients: 'Decision not to get vaccine made me ....' askedol'benefits.problemsmdaverall Scale 'Quality much worse/better than expected' 'Liltert scales“ 'Extremely well - Extremely poorly' 'Betterthci-Worsethan' 'Much better than - Much worse than' each standard 'Agree - Disagree' 'Mrchbetter-better-aboutthesame- worseomuchworse' 'Too high: Worsethm l thought-Accurate: Justeslexpecsed-Toolow: Betterthan Ithought' 'Worsethu'ilthoupht-justaslexpected— betterthanlthought' 'notaspood asexpected -better than expected' 'Mrchmoreseriousthanexpected-mch Ieesseriomtnanexpected' 'Hichleasthanetpected—chhgreeter thanexpected' 'Muchworseofftlmexpecsed—Aswellofl asupecteduMich better offthan expected' 'better than expected—worse than expected' Oliver and Bearden 1983 Oliver and Desarbo 1988 Oliver and Swan 1989 Olshavsky and Miller 1972 Patterson 1993 Parasuraman, Zeithaml. and Berry 1988 PM did Lounsbury 1984 Richins lid Bloch 1991 Spreng andOishavsky 1993 Swan and Mutin 1981 Tse and Wilton 1988 Westbrook 1980 Westbrook and Reilly 1978 Number Scale Pts. of items per item 4 10 22 ll-7 12 2. 29 7 70 Table 7, continued Question Asked re: overall. benefits only. problems only, and positive/negative surprise over performance Tvvo levels were experimentally manipulated. Asked to rate recorder 'compared to an ideal or perfect recorder.‘ ' NOTE: They claimed to be measuring performance. 7 attributes were frequency response. freedom from distortion. background noise level. flutter. speed control. fidelity for voice. fidelity for music. Also asked re: overall. (performance - std) for 10 attributes (performance minus desires). both measured on Likert scales (performance minus W) All measured on semantic differential scales Ldielled normative standards as 'normative expectations' and 'mmparative expectations' 11 attributes for resurrents. 7 for beer 'Thinking about the benefits you have experienced with thiscar.wouldyousaythesebenefitsvmi 'Thinkingmitmyproblemsyou havehadwith thiscarsinceyoupurchasadit.wouldyousay theseproblemswere..-‘ 'ln comparison w/ the quality level you expected. howwouldratetheperfomwiceofthiscemera with regard to (clarity, sharpness. color. and ovrall nudity) of the picture?‘ (asked for each) (performance ratings minus expectations) for 12 attributes (e.g., prestige. room of interior. fun to drive. engine power. etc.) Expectationsandperformnemeaauredonsematic differentialscalee '....overail....how close did the [product] come to your expectations.‘ 'Subjectsflrstaskedtolistgoodandbadpoints ofproducts. Askedonceforeachbenefit: Askedonceforeachdrawbacic 'Subjectsl'lrstaskedtolistgoodandbedpolnts ofproducts. Askedonceforeachbenefit: Askedonceforeachdrawbeck: Asked once for overalle aspects: Scale 'Greater than expected-Worse than expected' “Better than expected - Worse than expected' 'Worst possible - Best possible“ (pert ‘ ima) - (exp ° imp) 'Agree - Disagree' 'mch less than expected - Mich greater thanexpected' 'Mlch less serious than expected - Mich moreserious than expected' Morse than i expected' - 'better than i expected' 'Very much poored than expected - Very muchbetterthanexpected' 'mchlesathanlexpected-Aboutwhatl upected—Wchgreaterthanlexpected' 'mchmoreserious thanlexpected—About whatlexpected—Mlchiesssen'ousthm W 'Nuchbetterthanlexpected—Aboutasl upected-Muchworsethnlexpected' 'Muchbetterthanlexpected-Aboutasl expected-Wehwsetiwllexpected' 'Muchbetterthanlexpected-Aboutasl upectednmchworsetimlexpected' Classification of Studies which DISCONFIRHATION STANDARD Predictive Expectation Desire Ideal Product TYPO Norm Best Brand 71 Table 8 Include Disconfirmation CALCULATION IETHOD Subjective Anderson and Sullivan 1993 Babin, Darden, and Griffin 1993 Bearden and Teel 1983 Boiling and Woodruff 1988 Cadotte, Woodruff, 8: Jenkins 1987 Churchill and Suprenant 1982 Drdge and Halstead 1991 Oliver 1980 Oliver 1993 Oliver and Bearden 1983 Richins and Bloch 1991 Tse and Wilton 1988 Westbrook 1980 Westbrook and Reilly 1978 Spreng and Olshavsky 1993 Olshavsky and Miller 1972 Tse and W'Iton 1988 Boiling and Woodruff 1988 Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987 Boiling and Woodruff 1988 Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987 Derived Barbeau 1984 Brown and Swartz 1989 Oliver and DeSarbo 1988 Patterson 1993 Prakash and Lounsbury 1984 Swan and Martin 1981 Barbeau 1984 Parasuraman, Zeithaml, and Berry 1988 Prakash and Lounsbury 1984 Prakash and Lounsbury 1984 72 exposure to the product or service; after exposure, the subject is asked to rate performance, usually for the same attributes and using scales identical to those used to measure the standard. Disconfirmation is then calculated as the simple difference between performance and the standard. Positive differences indicate performance exceeded the standard and thus were positively disconfirmed. The reverse holds for negative differences. A few scholars have suggested that derived disconfirmation measures should be operationalized as the ratio of performance/standard rather than as a difference score (e.g., Bonoma 1987; Lele and Sheth 1987). Cooper, Cooper, and Duhan (1989) tested whether the ratio operationalization outperformed the difference operationalization, and found the latter to be superior according to a number of validity related criteria. Thus, derived disconfirmation is rarely operationalized as a ratio. Subjective disconfirmation has been criticized for one major reason. This measure allows subjects to alter their remembered standards or performance evaluations or both in a manner consistent with dissonance theory (Festinger 1957) or assimilation-contrast theory (Sherif and Hovland 1961). Such measures may include a significant amount of bias (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984), and thus may not accurately reflect the degree to which performance met or failed to meet some pre-experience standard. Derived measures have also been criticized for several reasons. First, such measures typically do not account for disconfirmation of standards of salient attributes for which no prior measurements were obtained. For example, if a study of satisfaction with an airline flight neglected to obtain pre-flight expectations regarding how smooth the flight is, post flight measurements of performance likewise would not capture customer evaluation 73 of this attribute. Second, derived measures are difference scores, which have been strongly criticized for problems of reliability, discriminant validity, and spurious correlations (Peter, Churchill, and Brown 1993). Another problem with the derived disconfirmation measure is empirical: such measures are only weakly related to satisfaction. This criticism appears to hold true even when the reliability problem is controlled (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984). The only studies which have found strong relationships between derived disconfirmation and satisfaction are those which do not include an independent construct for perceived performance in the model (e.g., Swan and Trawick 1981). The second dimen_sion of TJable 6 is the standard actually disconfirmed. Numerous standards have been proposed and tested. The following is a list of major disconfirmation standards proposed in the marketing literature: predictive expectations (e.g., Miller 1976), normative expectations (e.g., Granbois, Summers and Frazier 1977), deserved expectations (Miller 1977), ideal expectations (e.g., Tse and Wilton 1988), comparative expectations (laTour and Peat 1980), best brand expectations (e.g., Prakash and Lounsbury 1984), etc. Although most researchers seem to agree that disconfirmed expectations are what explains satisfaction, consensus has not been reached on this issue. For example, Woodruff, Cadotte, and Jenkins (1983) propose that performance norms play an important role in disconfirmation; the subject compares product performance with a normative ideal. According to that article, norms may be either brand-based or product-based. If product performance falls within a "zone of indifference," the normative explanation 74 is confirmed; if it falls outside the zone, disconfirmation occurs and leads to satisfaction or dissatisfaction. The degree to which expectations and norms relate, or whether one should be used rather than the other is open to debate (Hunt 1977). A related idea is proposed in LaTour and Peat (1979); they propose the Thibaut and Kelly concept of using a "comparison level" (C.L.) for calculating disconfirmation. The C.L. is based on all salient outcomes of the same or similar occurrences or products in the past; the C.L is continually updated based on new experiences. Satisfaction thus becomes a relative, not absolute, emotional state. A few studies have focused on directly comparing the performance of various standards of disconfirmation. These studies, and their results, are summarized next. Prakash and Lounsbury (1984) compared predictive expectations, normative expectations and comparative expectations in two different usage situations (fast food hamburger restaurants and beer). All disconfirmation constructs were operationalized as computational measures (i.e., differences between the pre usage and the post usage evaluation of performance). They concluded that normative and comparative expectation measures outperformed predictive expectations as predictors of satisfaction, though the evidence for the observed differential performance is weak. Barbeau (1984) compared predictive expectations, desires, and past experience as comparison standards in derived disconfirmation measures. Disconfirmation measures using desires and past experience were found to be a significant antecedent of satisfaction, while disconfirmation of predictive expectations was not. Swan and Trawick (1981) directly compared the explanatory power of derived ("inferred") versus subjective ("perceived") disconfirmation. Using a 75 series of regression equations, they concluded that both types of disconfirmation were significant, though derived disconfirmation appeared to outperform subjective disconfirmation in terms of explanatory power. However, it should be noted that the derived measure implicitly accounted for perceived performance; it is impossible to determine whether the operationalization of disconfirmation or the inclusion of performance accounted for the superior explanatory power of the derived versus subjective disconfirmation measure. Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins (1987) compared predictive expectations, product type norms and best brand norms as predictors of satisfaction in three different restaurant situations (fast food, family, and atmosphere). Disconfirmation constructs were operationalized as overall subjective measures. They concluded that product norm and best brand norms outperformed predictive expectations as a predictor of satisfaction; however, it should be noted that the evidence is equivocal given that none of the models estimated fit the data well. They also concluded that different standards may be relevant in different use situations or among different individuals in the same usage situation. Spreng and Olshavsky (1993) compared an expectations-based disconfirmation measure with a desires-based measure, desires congruency. Building on the work of Westbrook and Reilly (1983) and Barbeau (1984), they demonstrated, and theoretically supported, the superiority of the desires congruency measure as an antecedent of satisfaction. In their model, the effects of disconfirmation of expectations on satisfaction was not significant. 76 As we have seen, the traditional model of satisfaction formation depends heavily on the concept of disconfirmation. At its most basic level, disconfirmation is the difference between what a person expects (expectation) and what he or she receives (performance). Logically, only three things can vary in this definition: the definition of expectancy, the definition of performance, and the operationalization of the concept of "difference." The four most-commonly referred to theories in the satisfaction literature are utilized in an attempt to explain the relationship among these three constructs. Anderson (1973) examines what the four theoretical approaches say about the relationship of disconfirmed expectancy and perceived performance: 1) Cognitive dissonance theory specifies that a consumer will alter the perception of performance to make it more congruent with expectations. Therefore, low expectations will yield perceptions of lower performance; high expectations will yield perceptions of higher performance. 2) Contrast theory specifies that a consumer will intensify the disparity resulting from disconfirmed expectations. Therefore, negatively disconfirmed expectations will yield perceptions of higher performance; positively disconfirmed expectations will yield perceptions of lower performance. 3) Generalized negativity theory states that any deviation from expectations will result in a negative disconfirmation. 4) Assimilation-contrast theory specifies that slight-to-moderate deviations will result in perception of slightly higher or lower performance (higher for positive and lower for negative disconfirmation) as predicted by cognitive dissonance. However, as disconfirmation becomes more severe, the perceived difference between expectations and performance is magnified, and 77 the results predicted by contrast theory appear to hold. Anderson's own experiment supported assimilation-contrast theory. Oliver (1980) acknowledges that adaptation level theory appears to apply to the process of disconfirmation. The theory states that perception occurs in relation to an "adapted standard." Once established, this adaptation level serves as a standard for future evaluations. Oliver states that expectations, "however created" (p. 461), function as an adaptation level. Disconfirmation results when actual performance is compared to the adaptation level. Those few studies which have examined results in relation to these underlying theories have consistently found support for cognitive dissonance explanations (Festinger 1957) and for the assimilation explanations offered by assimilation-contrast theory (Sherif and Hovland 1961). For example, Olson and Dover (1979) express a fairly typical conclusion when they report that their results ".... support a dissonance theory prediction" and later, that their results "....indicate a consistent pattern of assimilation-like effects...." (p. 186). In summm, predictive expectation has been the most commonly used standard for the operationalization of disconfirmation. In addition, subjective measures have generally been found to be superior to derived measures of disconfirmation. Single-item measures of disconfirmation, either overall or at the attribute level, have been most commonly used in previous research. In this dissertation consistent with previous research, a single item, 7- point scale measurement of subjective disconfirmation will be used; the standard disconfirmed will be predictive expectations. 78 lI-4. Principle relationships among constructs In Sections II-2 and II-3, we examined individually the principle constructs utilized in traditional satisfaction models. In this section, relationships among the constructs are examined in detail. The section is organized around the direct relationships between possible antecedent variables and possible dependent variables. In Section II-4.1, the relationships between perceived performance and its possible antecedents are examined. In Section II-4.2, the relationships between disconfirmation and its possible antecedents are examined. Finally, in Section II-4.1, the relationships between satisfaction and its possible antecedents are examined. II-4. l . Antecedents of perceived performance: Expectations, Desires, and Attitudes Researchers have been aware that the perception of performance (or product quality) can be affected by prior expectations. For example, Anderson (1973) demonstrates that the rating of product quality of a particular item is higher if expectations of quality are high and lower if expectations of quality are low. Olshavsky and Miller (1972) demonstrate similar results using a different product. However, the link to customer satisfaction was not made. This may be because the researchers think the link is obvious, or it may be due to a lack of interest in customer satisfaction until the early 1970's (Hunt 1977). Table 9 lists the studies which modeled antecedents of performance along with the product/ service context, sample composition and analytical methods. Columns to the right of the Method column refer to possible antecedents of perceived performance. The numbers in these columns indicated the relative strength of relationship between the antecedent and 79 Eozsaiwev F Foucaeuotoq 8288a co oucmctotoa 35:98.: Fouozv F jcasb a fiauu< ou35m< macaw mucaN F 58 80329.8 80328.8 man-«Fa £8 Foo—8.50:3 8288a co cow—3898 38.33an ”3028 850 02.3..an N F F F F 988 F 2.8 F 2.8 F F 2,88... <>Oz< 33am .>OU .uuaum .>OU 88:. .8 88:. .8 32% $8 32% $8 82% $3 533.62 8.329.. 53852 F563.“ 3:33.» 8563.». 8085...... E38 muCOUSHm 82805 8259..." 353% 353% ggugu mac—Dug ”BF—Bug 353% 353% gggu £83» .935 882 809 Jam: U02 any. 882. 25: 85¢ 32 mini 89> new... 82. neon .umm. 008 emu.— .quL 000.— umfl am». too“— was; ..go 0958 83 08:3. 3883 0.3.2: £80 gggllluflfiwlllfiuflfi e 882:8»? 8;; as at w ... .N 882:3»? b.5833 .28 5888 m .m .F tooz..?mmF £583.. 88 £885 88F 8888 8:25:58? 3580:. baa. Sn sausage oucaEBtoa 2:82: 8 0058B 2058 ”302 at: .2... .28 39238 N 800213me 35:05.3 van ___FU.=EUV F BEIANQmF pancake—Fm 0:5 55538 N 382:5? 8888 FavozsammF 8888 m .ouozstmmF 83:8 8a 5280; .8888 N 38:..FBmF 8:8 8a 5.88; .3888 F moozzFBmF 83:8 88 £285 6888 ~ 382132 38.88 F .80stng 3.88 AmmmF 52:3 new combuc_ua_omloocmE._o.F._on_ Fo macoumoouc< m «33 80 performance. If a relationship was tested and reported to be not significant, a "0" appears in the appropriate column. The following observations can be made regarding Table 9. 1) Studies which examined the expectations-perceived performance relationship found the relationship to be significant. It should be noted that in Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins (1987), expectations was reported to be a significant covariate of performance; it was not hypothesized to be an antecedent in that study. Also, Olshavsky and Miller (1972) report a significant effect of expectation on perceived performance, but the dependent variable they actually measured was disconfirmation. Still, the evidence linking expectations and performance presented in the table is strong. 2) Two sLtudies examined the strengh of predictive expectation_s on performgnce relative to the strength of other potential antecedents on performance. Prakash and Lounsbury (1984) investigated the relative importance of predictive expectations versus other types of expectations. Only in the case of Tse and Wilton (1988) was expectations found not to be the most important antecedent. Not surprisingly, Tse and Wilton found that manipulated performance was a more powerful antecedent of perceived performance than was expectations. 3) Barbeau (1984) is the only study which examines the relationship between desires and performance, and the relationship is reported to be nonsignificant. It is difficult to make any generalizations about the desires - performance relationship given that it has been tested so infrequently in the literature. 81 In this dissertation perceived performance is measured in one of the models and, consistent with the satisfaction literature, predictive expectation is included as a potential antecedent. II-4.2. Antecedents of disconfirmation: Expectations, Desires, Attitudes, and Perceived Performance Table 10 illustrates exactly which standards are being disconfirmed in each of the studies reviewed. Table 11 illustrates how expectations compare with desires, attitudes, and performance as antecedents of disconfirmation in the studies reviewed. Table 1 1 lists studies which model antecedents of disconfirmation along with the product/ service context, sample composition and basic analytical methods used. Columns to the right of the Method column contain possible antecedents of disconfirmation. The numbers in these columns indicates the relative strength of relationship between the antecedent and disconfirmation. Thus, for example, in Churchill and Surprenant (1982)-—Model 1 (plant), expectation had a stronger relationship with disconfirmation than did perceived performance, yet both relationships were statistically significant. If a relationship was tested and reported to be not significant, a "O" is used in the appropriate column. The following observations can be made from Table 10 and Table 11. 1) With the exception of Churchill and Surprenant (1982)-Model 1, whenever expectations and perceived performance appeared in a model together, the relationship between expectations_and disconfirmation was weaker than the relationship between perceived performance and disconfirmation. Given that disconfirmation is an evaluative response to performance, this finding should not be surprising. 82 Table 10 Antecedents of Disconfirmation -- Standards Disconfirmed STANDARD DISCONFIRBED Experience/ Product Best Predictive Type Brand Study Expectatia Desire Ideal Norm Norm OthL (Anderson and Sullivan 1993) V (Barbeau 1984) V V V (Bolling and Woodruff 1988) V V V (Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987)-Model 1 V (Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987)-Model 2 V (Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987)-Model 3 V (Churchil and Surprenant 1982)—plant V (Churchill and Surprenant 1982)-video player V (Oliver 1980)-Model 1 V (Oliver 1980)-Model 2 \/ (Oliver and Bearden 1983)-Model 1 V (Oliver and Bearden 1983)-Model 2 V (Olshavsky and Miller 1972) Note: authors claimed to measure performance V evaluation but really measured disconfirmation (Patterson 1993)) V (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984)-Model 1 V (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984)-—Model 2 V (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984)-Model 3 V (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984)--Model 4 V (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984)-—Model 5 V (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984)-Model 6 V (Spreng and Olshavsky 1993) V V (Swan & Trawick 1981)-0V is derived discon. (Swan 3. Trawick 1981)-0V is subjective discon. 1 (derived) (T se and Wilton 1988)-Model 4 V V V 83 1.80.2...82 8...... 8.. at .58... 3.8.33 m. 5:202 8.35 08 8:8 .88... 8.4.8 m. >0.-. 62 .935 8a 8:8 8.38:8... 8.9220 8.. 82%. 22868.6:88. 8.2.9.8 8.. 9.2%. m .88..-.32 .0382: 8. .88.... m .88.--ng .5853 8a 89...... e 80.2.-.32 .5353 8a .88.... m 82:32 .9853 u... .88.... N 82:82 58...... 8a :88... F 82:82 .38.... 8. 58.8... .82 .8288... 8.8.6.28»... 8.88... .28. 5.. 8.09.26 8.8.52.8 0580... 8 88.30 2058 .802 .22 .2: 8a 8.9558 N 3821.82 $0.8m 832.8 F 802.82 ..888 82.2.8 N 382:.82 82.8 F .88....82 ......8 F 82:38. 5829... 82.258 288182 29.803 82.588 m 38.7.52 23...... 8.. £0.80; 63088 N 38.72.02 2.....2 8.. «3.825 .3888 F .ouozitmmF 23.8 8.. 53.08.... 65088 memF cog-am Pa c8093. F o o 58 2.003... .93... 0.000. N c0335... don duo .5383. F 00.8060. don ....ou 2.9338. F .80.... .>00 3503a 8058 F N 80.8 .>00 3503a p.068 .88... F 2.0.58.8 3:036 .08 .....o... F 25.8.8.8 8:83» .03. 8o. 03. F535 F 2.0.52.8 3.003% .03 .....o... F 2.98.2.8 3588 .82 80. .8. F «00.8.8.8 35030 .03 F 2.0.52.8 8:033 .30. poo. an! F N 58 88205.. 288.. 00:25.58... €225.58... .0 8.88.8.0... :0 00330098 .8388... .202. 005.58... .802. . N (52... 3888 .93... as o 5.... 383...... .8 so... 0 £8 v.8: .... 8... o 58 8:003... 8.89 ...... 0 San 80...:ch 8.08.. 0.. F N .828 500 8080.7. .250 000$ N F .60.“ $00 2835 8a... F .83... N .628 .>00 800.0030 .80. .000. an! F .820 .8... N .628 .8 808890 .80. 000. .8. F N .628 .>0u £00.83“. .80. 000. «no. E2588 3032a . N 8.93.8. 5.8.5 295... Iguana: add. Jag: nag: flag I.. umflufl gala]. llmlxmucou 0028.8 .25 02.0.00... |§§1 F F 03a... a 02.3.09... 3.8.3.--c0.ua........00m.o ..0 30000035.. 84 The Churchill and Surprenant (1982)-Model 1 (plant) finding that expectation had a larger impact on disconfirmation than did performance may be due to the magnitude of manipulations used in that experiment. In the artificial environment in which the authors had complete control over both the magnitude of expectation and performance, it is reasonable to believe that expectations could be manipulated to dominate performance in the relationship. The absence of similar findings in any field study or in any other experiment indicates such is probably the case. On the other hand, Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins (1987) find a significant causal path from expectation to disconfirmation for all three restaurant settings they examine (p. 312), though it should be pointed out that all of the LISREL models they constructed resulted in poor goodness of fit measures for the entire model. 2) In most models tested, expectations were significantly related to disconfirmation. Those studies which tested for this relationship but failed to find it were Oliver (1980), Oliver and Bearden (1983), Bearden and Teel (1983) and Tse and Wilton (1988). These three studies appear to differ from the others in two regards. First, they are the only three studies to use path analysis as the major analytical method. It is unclear why this particular analytical method should be so strongly associated with this particular result. Second, all three of these studies used presumably highly-involving products/services as the study context. It may be possible that for highly involving targets, expectations and disconfirmation are independent. However, two other studies, Churchill and Surprenant (1982) and Olshavsky and Miller (1972), also used durable goods as product contexts. (It should be pointed out that in the later study, the authors claimed to measure "perceived performance" as the 85 dependent variable, not "disconfirmation.") One observation is clear: none of the studies which used one-time services or non—durable goods 23 study contexts failed to find a relationship between expectjtion and disconfirmation. It may be that for product/ service contexts in which involvement is likely to be relatively low, expectations become a significant antecedent of disconfirmation. If involvement is low, actual performance may be less important relative to expectations in affecting disconfirmation because there is less perceived variance in performance or because people care less about performance. 3) Note that desires is never modelew an antecedent of disconfirmation probably because desires have seldomly appeared at all in satisfaction models until recently. Desire is included in Spreng (1992), Spreng and Olshavsky (1993) and Spreng, Dixon, and Olshavsky (1993). In all these studies, desire is modeled as an antecedent of desires congruity rather than expectation disconfirmation. 4) Attitude is tested in only two models as an antecedent of disconfirmation. In both models, it is found not to be significantly related to satisfaction. In this dissertation, expectations will be modeled as an antecedent of disconfirmation in both models. Perceived performance will be modeled as an antecedent in one model. Despite its absence in previous satisfaction models, desires will be modeled as an antecedent of disconfirmation for reasons discussed in Chapter III. Attitude will not be included as an antecedent of disconfirmation. 86 Il-4.3 . Antecedents of satisfaction: Expectations, Desires, Attitudes, Perceived Performance, and Disconfirmation Tables 12, 13, and 14 illustrates the direct effects of all modeled antecedents on satisfaction. In Table 12, the first four columns indicate study, product/ service context, sample composition, and analytical method, respectively. In Table 13, the first column again refers to the study. The next three columns indicate the pre-performance antecedents: predictive expectations, other expectations, and desires. The next column refers to perceived performance. The next four columns all refer to disconfirmation, with a separate disconfirmed standard listed for each column. As in previous tables demonstrating relationships between constructs, numbers in columns for each study indicate the relative strength of relationship between that antecedent and satisfaction. A "0" indicates that the relationship between that antecedent and satisfaction was examined and found to be non-significant. In Table 14, following the column indicating study, the next two columns indicate whether the disconfirmation measure used was derived or measured subjectively. In the last column, other independent variables included in the model are listed. The following observations may be made with regard to direct antecedents of satisfaction. 1) It apgars that perceived performance is consistently found to have the largest impact on satisfaction. In all but four of the studies which examined the relationship between perceived performance and satisfaction, perceived performance had the largest direct effect on satisfaction. The three studies in which perceived performance had the second strongest impact on satisfaction were all experiments in which performance was manipulated. The reduced 87 Table 1 2 Characteristics of Studies Testing Antecedents of Satisfaction Study Contgrt Saer Lemod (Anderson and Sulivan 199 3) multiple Sweden regression promcts consumers (Barbeau 1980—Model 1 course eval. students recession (Barbeau 1980-Model 2 course eval. students recession (Bearden and Teel 1983)—Model 1 auto repair gen. pop. cov. struct. (Bearden and Teel 1983)—Model 2 auto repair gen. pop. cov. struct. (Bitner 1990) travel agent gen. pop. path (Bolling and Wooduff 1988) wine gen. pop. recession (Cadotte, Wooctuff, and Jenkins 1987)-Model 1 fast food rest. gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cadotte, Wooduff, and Jenkins 1987)-Model 2 fast food rest. gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cadotte, Wooduff, and Jenkins 1987)-Model 3 fast food rest. gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cardozo 1965)—Model 1 pens students (if. means (Cardozo 1965)—-Model 2 pens snidents (if. means (Churdiill and Surprenant 1982)-Model 1 plant gen. pop. cov. struct. (Churdiil and Surprenant 1982)—Model 2 video player gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cronin and Taylor 1992)—Model 1 banking gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cronin and Taylor 1992)-Model 2 pest control gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cronin and Taylor 1992)—Model 3 dy deaning gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cronin and Taylor 1993-Model 4 fast food gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cronin and Taylor 1992)-Model 5 banking gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cronin and Taylor 1992)—Model 6 pest control gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cronin and Taylor 1992)-Model 7 try cleaning gen. pop. cov. struct. (Cronin and Taylor 1992)-Model 8 fast food gen. pop. cov. struct. (Drbge and Halstead 1991)—Model 1 carpet non-complainers cov. struct. (Drbge and Halstead 1991)—-Model 2 carpet complainers cov. struct. (Fisk and Young 1985)-Modd 1 air travel gen. pop. ANOVA (Fbk and Young 1983—Model 2 air travel gen. pop. ANOVA (Fisk and Young 1985)—Model 3 air travel student ANOVA (Fisk and Young 1985)—Model 4 air travel student ANOVA (Garland and Westbrook 1989) library svc. students cov. struct. 88 Table 12, continued Stlfiy Comm Sam e Method (Giver 1980)—Model 1 flu vaccine gen. pop. path (Oliver 1980)-Model 2 flu vaccine students path (Oliver 1993)-Model 1 automobile gen. pop. cov. struct. (Oliver 1993)-Model 2 class student cov. struct. (Oliver and Bearden 1983)—Model 1 Get pill users path (Oliver and Bearden 1989-Model 2 Get piI non-users path (Oliver and Desarbo 1988) stock returns students ANOVA (Oiver and L'nda 1981)-Model 1 pajamas gen. pop. - males path (Oliver and Linda 1981)-Model 2 pajamas gen. pop. - males path (Oliver and Linda 1981)-Model 3 pajamas gen. pop. - females path (Oliver and Linda 1981)—Model 4 pajamas gen. pop. - females path (Oliver and Swan 1989) (same data as Swan and Oliver. 1991 - see below) (Olshavsky and filler 1972) tape player students ANOVA (Patterson 1993) home remnt path heaters purchasers (Prakash and Lounsbury 1980—Model 1 fast food rest. snidents correlations (Prakash and Lounsbury 1980-Model 2 beer students correlations (Prakash and Lounsbury 1984)-Model 3 fast food rest. students correlations (Prakash and Lounsbury 1980—Model 4 beer students correlations (Prakash and Lounsbury 1980-Model 5 fast food rest. students correlations (Prakash and Lounsbury 1980-Model 6 beer students correlations (Richins and Bloch 1991 )—Model 1 automobile gen. pothi involv. correlations (Richins and Bloch 1991)-Model 2 automobile gen. pop./lo involv. correlations (Richins and Bloch 1990-Model 3 automobile gen. pop/hi involv. correlations (Ridiins and Bloch 1991)—Model 4 automob'de gen. pop/lo involv. correlations Table 1 2, continued 89 Study Contfl Saer Mpthod (Spreng and Olshavsky 1993) camera students cov. struct. (Swan and Martin 1981) automobile student regeesion (Swan and Oliver 1991) automobile new purchasers correlations (Swan and Trawidr 1981) restaurant gen. pop. regession (Tse and Wilton 1988)-Model 4 record player student path (Westbrook 1980)—Model 1 automobiles student regession (Westbrook 1980)—Model 2 footware student regession Note: author claimed to measure expectation but really measured disconfirmation (Westbrook 1981) stores gen. pop. factor analysis (Westbrook and Newman 1978) shopping process gen. pop. regression (Westbrook and Reilly 1983) automobile students cov. struct. 90 o F o 8.3.9.68. e585...» 9... ...5558 P N m €29.6me Eases e5 .....osco. N aging, 88.8. Faeozlfimm. 2838 _ 22811.32 2.58.. 23 £38; .8638 F N 3351.32 2:54 2... £38; .3638 P . 3221.89 2.35% 213583.388. P o o as... .82 .32.. 9182 :38: e5 9.508 o P o 9.2.. .5 .32.. 3.8»? :88; ...... 9539 P N o :5: .85 62.3182 :58: Ba 96.8. N P o 9.8.. .88 .62.. $182 :58; use 9.58. P N o 9.8.. .5 .32.. #182 .258; e5 95.8. N P o :8: .8... .32.. #182 .2583 Ha 95.8. N F N wooing. .8» Ba 828$ N P F wooing. .9: us. 8288 N F o N 38.132 8258 F o o P muesli... 388$ N P .82 52...“ 2a 885v 682 :32 «would. a? x .3: mi .314]... :2 jam an an“ 53W 22m a...» 3.6.8... a??? 850 Eden; 63 88a: SEEN 3%... .u. J33 oocmtoag o>3£oxlc030£m3am Co mucouooeuc< mp 03a... 91 .88 88535.8 .9... e .o N 2 P F F 2 p N P o 5.62 lEbz jun flawglxm 3.5 a... I loulzuqu < '38 g g 9.2.. 82 28.8... 8.83.. .25 .288... 8m 632.. 85:85 3 J3 cozczcoo .mp 033. N 8851.82 82.0. . 82.1.82 32.0. 58.88 - .82 82.0. 28 - .82 82.0. . 82 88...... .82 92:82 Ba 8898... Swap .8953; vs Una—.30. e 88182 9.8» 9... 8... m 882.82 9.8» 9... 8.... N 8.182 9.8» 9... 8.... 2 821.82 9.8» 9... 8.... .82 288.2. N .2811. 82 888...: .95 «9.5. P 802:. 32 988.2. 9... 985. a 92 .Eoz Ilegll .980. 8.4g 9...... 9.... 288... “men 630k. 805.0805 3 PFFP F _. NNNN lleolllllicngba 80332 2.80 liege xm an.“ x 03.88.. 850 85888.5 3% 08:59.00 .m_. 038.. .82 888.8... .22 8.....-9... gfifi. .88.. 8... - .8. 82.0 98 .88 9. 38 8.8. .82 .82.. 98 82.0. a 8...... 52 8...: 9... 82.0. m 8821.62 8.... 98 82.0. N 8821.62 «9.... 98 82.0. F 88:... 82 8...: 9... 82.0. .82 8.88 98 82.0. ~ BqulAmomp 50.8w new L62.0. — .ouoc‘lammmp cooeaom new 82.0. N Bootlammmp 83.0. .. SOIIAmmmP 32.0. Ham 93 e .300... 8...... N ”22930 8:8 N "8:93 8...... .. .330... 8.3... m N . 0 N 88.88888... N\_ _\N N\. ~\_ N . N . N 2 N P m P m P 6.02 6.02 .8. .|_8q leogfixd I 8. . emcee; ll. 9...... a...» 2.8.8.. 9288.. 88 88.. 80:8..on 1%: .. z ......8. m ......8. m ....8... m .58... m N N 803...... 8.80 lava xm Idem—'00.... .0 850 2,88... 4% 08:52.00 .m_. 83.... .82 82.0 9... 52w. .59 ...th 05 Sam. .82 598.0 9... 988w. e 882... 82 .8... 9... 8.8.... m 8......82 .8... 98 8.8.... N 821.82 8... 9... 8.8.... p 8.182 .8... 98 2.6.... e $.82 8828.. 9... .89.“... m 8.21.82 2:88.. 98 28.2.. .. 8821.82 2888.. 98 .898... m 821.82 289.8. 9... 82...... N 8:...82 8398.. 9... .88... 2 821.82 289.8. 9... .88.... 63w 94 m — 5.02 8.02 8.000 Illlglcozfiu .6 988 25 2.8.9:. .80 828.. 00000096 03332 .0 llll00ca§¢ .8388. 00:50:00 .mp 030... to N 0030?. 0.000 :0. ....filxm lung... xm 0050 02.8.60... .89 .....8. .28 ..8.£8.s. 0008:3080! 00.0080... 2.80. 50 00030098 0.300... 8 008.20 .05.... .802 N $802 .8983. . $.00... .8553. 8 09.5188. 8...; 98 at Camp .930... 0:0 ..ng 063$ 95 > > \z > > > \z > > 2850202. > > > 0:003:58 9.5302828 > > > \z > > > > > > > > > > ......z lqlg ...0 02 null» .8280 2.80.4.0. 0 28.. .0 ... 88.0880 8.. 0.). .050 0_000_2 :0503033 :_ an< .30 Ed ZO.hU > > > > > > > > > ~. ~ .... ... w .... .... ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~. ~ N.. > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > 2... I199... 02 In.» 9.2.8 In...>_8...m..|m 88.. ... ... 88.9.8 8.. Hm? 5w am ZOFU>>> > >>>>>> 550020.305... .. . ... > > \z > >7» >> Ea: 065w m2 00> 053. .0 9 «002055 00: > >>>>>> >>>> w 0.? .050 20....U>>> >>>>>> 00.93.20... >> >> a ZOF(!¢IZOUw.o 80:50:00 .3. 030.. 8 882... S2 .89.. 98 8.8.... m 89.2.82 .89.. 98 8.6.... N 89.2... 82 .89.. 98 8.6.... . 882. 82 .890 98 9....9... 0 89.2.82 ... 89.2.52 8 89.2.52 8 89.2.52 N 80.2.82 . 89.2.9.2 238.9... 98 .898... 299.9... 98 .898... 298...... 98 .898... 298...... 98 .898... 298...... 98 89.9.. 239...... 98 .898... .82 8.8.8.. .320... 000 - Pam» £025 new 22.5 an 38 OER... 3mm» 2026 9.0 .025. 3mm» 00.0000 9.0 82.0. ......88.82 .8980 98 82.0. 8.8.9.2 .8980 98 82.0. N BUOZIAmmmP $2.0. _. BOOIIAmmmF .025. .635 98 2 8...: ... .8 8:... 0:0 :ucuucoomn... 8.. 820.380.... ".8... .58.... 0> 803.50 03:22.80 0... 8.3. 2,202.0 83.2.... 2.5...ch 8.680 62.80 > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > > .....2 Imlg ...... .z in... 8...... Illfll.>..... ... 88.... .. 88.9.... 8: m.). .050 mar—.0 = 6 Eu 20.5(uw_h Satisfaction, Attitude -> Satisfaction, and Disconfirmation -> Satisfaction. H3c: Among Clinton voters, the following path will be significant and positive in explaining satisfaction with Bush: Disconfirmation -> Satisfaction. H3d: Among Bush voters, the following paths will be significant in explaining satisfaction with Clinton: Expectations -> Disconfirmation (negative), Desires-> Disconfirmation (positive), Expectations -> Satisfaction (negative), Desires -> Satisfaction (positive), Attitude -> Satisfaction (positive), and Disconfirmation -> Satisfaction (positive). H3c: Among Bush voters, the following paths will be significant in explaining satisfaction with Bush: Expectations -> Disconfirmation (negative), Desires-> Disconfirmation (negative), Expectations -> Satisfaction (negative), Desires -> Satisfaction (negative), Attitude -> Satisfaction (negative), and Disconfirmation -> Satisfaction (positive). In the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model, only one relevant pre- election construct is measured: expectations. Therefore, the research hypothesis prediction is straightforward. Expectations will be significant predictors of disconfirmation only among those from each voter group who are dissatisfied with the process (Figure 13); among those from each voter group who are satisfied with the process, expectations will be unrelated to 135 Figure 13 Hypothesized Paths in the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model for Those Dissatisfied with the Process Expectations, perceived performance and disconfirmation for campaign elements relative to each candidate are hypothesized to affect overall satisfaction, for dissatisfied Clinton supporters apg Bush supporters. 136 post-performance constructs (Figure 14). Notice that the relevant subgroups to test the research hypothesis are not Clinton versus Bush voters. Unlike the EOSM, in which there should be a close relationship between voting behavior and satisfaction with the outcome, satisfaction with the process is less related to voting behavior. It is quite reasonable for a Clinton supporter to be dissatisfied with Clinton's advertising effectiveness and running an unfair campaign, yet still be satisfied with the outcome of the election. Because the research hypothesis is stated in terms of satisfied versus dissatisfied consumers, it is necessary to test the hypothesis using Clinton versus Bush voters who are satisfied versus dissatisfied with the process as a classification variable. Specific testable hypotheses using the CPSM, therefore are the following: H3f: Among those who are satisfied with the process, expectation will not be a significant predictor of perceived performance or subjective disconfirmation for any campaign element of either target's campaign. H3g: Among those who are dissatisfied with the process, expectation will be a significant predictor of perceived performance (positive path) and subjective disconfirmation (negative path) for both campaign elements of each target's campaign. Alternatively, if small group sizes preclude analysis based on two two- group analyses as planned, hypotheses will be tested using an analysis of correlation coefficients. Note that this research hypothesis does not state that it is satisfaction or dissatisfaction per se which causes the increased processing; the question of causation is explicitly addressed in the discussion (Chapter VI), but it is not 137 Figure 14 Hypothesized Paths in the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model for Those Satisfied with the Process Perceived performance and (isconfirmation (but M expectations) for campaign elements relative to each candidate are hypothesized to affect overall satisfaction, for satisfied Clinton supporters M Bush supporters. 138 addressed in this hypothesis. Rather, level of processing is hypothesized to be associated with level of satisfaction. Likewise, the issue of using level of satisfaction for segmentation purposes is not addressed here, as key elements of segments (e.g., stability) are not investigated in this research. III-2.4 Theme No. 4: Importance of Desires versus Expectations in Satisfaction Formation Until recently, the traditional satisfaction literature has focused primarily on cognitive antecedents of satisfaction formation. Thus, expectations are hypothesized to affect satisfaction both directly and indirectly through disconfirmation. Recent authors have suggested that desires, too, are important antecedents of satisfaction (see Chapter II-3.2). The conditions under which one or the other might dominate the satisfaction formation process has not been resolved. It could be argued that on issues of great importance, the effects of desires would exceed the effects of expectations on satisfaction. Individuals have more at stake on issues of great importance and it is logical that performance congruent with desires would be a major antecedent of satisfaction. If someone who has just bought a house wants quiet neighbors but expects to have noisy neighbors, and the neighbors are quiet, the person is likely to be satisfied. If the neighbors are noisy, the person is likely to be slightly dissatisfied even though the expectations are being exactly confirmed. See Chapter II—3.2 for a complete discussion of recent developments on this issue. 139 Figure 1 1 illustrates the traditional model modified to include desires. It specifies relationships among expectations, desires, subjective disconfirmation, and satisfaction. It is hypothesized that desires are negatively related to disconfirmation. This hypothesis may appear to be unreasonable because "disconfirmation" is really "disconfirmation of predictive expectations." The question arises of why "desired performance level" can affect the degree to which observed performance was "better/worse than expected performance level." Consider subjective disconfirmation and how it is usually operationalized. If disconfirmation truly was the difference between actual performance and predictive expectation, then the hypothesis would be unreasonable. However, subjective disconfirmation encompasses a judgment of the degree to which remembered predictive expectations are met by perceived performance and an evaluation of any difference perceived. It seems reasonable to think that desires might affect a consumer's memory of what was expected, the perception of performance, and the evaluation of the disparity between perceived performance and expectation. In other words, desires can affect memory, perception, and judgment - three key elements in how subjective disconfirmation is operationalized. The research hypothesis proposed in this thesis is that the direct and total effects of desires on satisfaction will exceed the direct and total effects of expectations on satisfaction, given that the target is generally perceived to be important. When individuals have strong desires, it seems obvious that their ultimate level of satisfaction will at least be somewhat dependent on these desires. As demonstrated throughout Chapter II, when expectations is the only pre-performance construct measured, it is found to play a major role in the satisfaction formation process. These findings are especially strong in 140 laboratory studies in which variance in desires is likely to be minimal, and/ or when the target is of relatively slight importance. However when desires are included along with expectations as potential antecedents of satisfaction, the disconfirmation of desires is found to be significant (e.g., Barbeau 1987; Spreng 1990; Spreng and Olshavsky 1993), and disconfirmation of expectations is not significant. Further, Spreng (1990) has pointed out that one possible reason for failure to find support for the effects of desires on satisfaction is the difficulty involved in attempting to manipulate consumer desires in a laboratory setting. Without the ability to introduce variance in desires, one popular traditional avenue of conducting satisfaction research has been unproductive in investigating this relationship. Likewise in field studies, variance in desires has been difficult to establish in traditional consumer satisfaction studies, probably for reasons similar to those behind finding minimal variance in measures of satisfaction (Peterson and Wilson 1992). Just as there is slight variance in satisfaction measures in empirical studies because most consumers are satisfied with most purchases, there may be slight variance in desires because most people desire the same things: high quality, good service, low price, etc. For these reasons, the Election Outcome Satisfaction Model provides a uniquely favorable set of circumstances for testing the research hypothesis. Specifically, variance in both satisfaction and desires is virtually guaranteed in a presidential election: large proportions of people are as likely to be dissatisfied as satisfied with the election outcome. Since it is likely that most voters consider the presidential election to be an important event, the research hypothesis indicates that desire should dominate expectation as an 141 antecedent of satisfaction; this should be true for both supporters of Bush and supporters of Clinton. Specific testable hypotheses, therefore, are: H4a: The magnitude of the desires -> satisfaction path will be greater than the magnitude of the expectation -> satisfaction path for both targets among Clinton voters. H4b: The magnitude of the desires -> satisfaction path will be greater than the magnitude of the expectation -> satisfaction path for both targets among Bush voters. H4c: The total effects, direct and indirect, of desires on satisfaction will exceed the total effects of expectation on satisfaction for both targets among Clinton voters. H4d: The total effects, direct and indirect, of desires on satisfaction will exceed the total effects of expectation on satisfaction for both targets among Bush voters. III-3. Models to test hypotheses These four research hypotheses are to be tested in one or both of two models. Testable hypotheses for each research hypothesis and each model have been presented throughout Section III-2. An overview of each complete model is presented next. Construct operationalizations appear in Chapter IV. III-3.1. Election Outcome Satisfaction Model The complete Election Outcome Satisfaction Model is presented in Figure 15. Where applicable, hypothesized signs of each path are indicated. Also, the related testable hypotheses are identified for each path. Attitude toward Clinton Expectations 142 Satisfaction w/ re: Clinton Desires re: Clintons's Performance D .. nflrrnatlon w/ Clintons‘s Performance Clinton Desires re: Bush 0,- Overall Satisfaction Disconfirmation w/ Bush's Performance Satisfaction w/ Bush's Expectations re: Bush Attitude Bush Performance 0,‘ c,- Figure 1 5 Complete Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Note: First sign is the hypothesized sign for Clinton supporters and the second sign is the hypothesized sign for Bush supporters. 143 III-3.2. Campaign Process Satisfaction Model The complete Campaign Process Satisfaction Model is presented in Figure 16. Where applicable, hypothesized signs of each path have been indicated. Also, the related testable hypotheses have been identified for each path. Construct operationalizations and complete model specifications are presented in the next chapter. For ease of reference, the four major research hypotheses are summarized once again: (1) Multiple targets of satisfaction are relevant to the overall satisfaction formation process. (2) Processes relevant to the formation of satisfaction with competing alternatives are structurally interrelated. ( 3) Dissatisfied consumers process more extensively than do satisfied consumers. (4) When the target of satisfaction is relatively important, the effects of desires will dominate effects of expectations on the entire satisfaction formation process. 144 Figure 16 Complete Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Expectations, perceived performance and disconfirmation for campaim elements relative to each candidate are hypothesized to affect overall satisfaction, for both Clinton supporters and Bush supporters. Chapter IV Method This chapter is divided into three sections. In the first section, data collection methods and the critical issue of timing are discussed. The second section presents operationalizations of key constructs for the Election Outcome Satisfaction Model. The third section contains similar information for the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model. IV—l. Data Collection and Timing To test the research hypotheses developed in the previous chapter, data were collected at two points in time: pre-election information was collect in September, 1992, and post-election information was collected in November, 1992, immediately following the election. Data were collected by MBA students at Michigan State University and the University of Kentucky for course credit and under the supervision of course professors. Each student was directed to contact five acquaintances and administer the pre-election questionnaire in- person or by telephone. Following the election, students recontacted each respondent and administered the post-election questionnaire. A total of 331 pre-election questionnaires were completed while 303 usable post-election questionnaires were completed. The discrepancy of 28 is due to respondents of the pre-election sample not voting in the November election. Only respondents who completed both pre- and post-election questionnaires are included in this analysis. Although questionnaires administered via personal contact are not new to consumer research in general, they have not been utilized in field studies of 145 146 satisfaction formation. For this particular context, personal contact is the preferred method of data collection. In the 1992 presidential campaign process, significant developments occurred weekly and it is likely that history effects could have jeopardized data from a mail-out survey due to the typically wide variance in response times. Personally contacting respondents enabled tight control of the timing of data collection to minimize the chance that respondents would be differentially affected by media stories. The most obvious illustration of this potential confound is the behavior of candidate Ross Perot. Mr. Perot was a candidate for president throughout early 1992, withdrew from the race in the summer and re-entered the race in September. Had a mailout survey been distributed during the period Mr. Perot was not a candidate, it is almost certain that some respondents would have answered while he was out of the race and some would have responded after he re-entered the race. Measures of expectations and desires would have been rendered noncomparable as the dynamics of the campaign radically shifted with the single event of Mr. Perot's re—entering the race. Similarly, expectations regarding advertising effectiveness and running an unfair campaign would likely change on a weekly basis as the campaign entered it final month. likewise, the possibility of major events occurring following the election (e.g., increasing U.S. involvement in Somalia or Bosnia) illustrates the need to complete all post-election data collection in a short time period, too. Therefore, minimizing the variance in data collection timing is important to addressing the research questions, and personally contacting respondents to collect data is the most appropriate technique for accomplishing this objective. 147 Some may question whether the snowball sample selection methodology used here resulted in a "representative sample." Kerlinger (1986) defines a representative sample as one which "....has approximately the characteristics of the population relevant to the research in question" (p. 11 1). If one was interested in predicting population voting patterns or in describing the demographics of the population of voters, then this sample would not be considered representative. However, testing the research hypotheses in this dissertation does not require a representative sample in this sense. All research hypotheses involve relationships among key constructs and thus the absolute magnitude of population proportion or mean values is not relevant. All that is required is that the relationships between theoretical constructs not vary systematically between the sample and a relevant population, and there is no reason to suspect that such systematic differences might exist here. As long as external validity is of secondary importance in a particular research endeavor, as it is here, convenience samples are considered to be adequate for theory testing purposes (Calder, Phillips and Tybout, 1982). IV-2. Operationalization of Key Constructs In this section, the operationalization of key constructs for each model is presented and discussed. Table 15 lists all constructs in a matrix so that the appropriate model and the timing of measurements is clear. Issues related to the operationalizations of constructs are discussed in Section 4.2.1 for the Election Outcome Satisfaction Model (EOSM), and in Section 4.2.2, for the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model (CPSM). Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Campaign Process Satisfaction Model 148 Table 15 Operationalization of Constructs Timing of Measurements for Each Model Measured Before Measured After the Election the Election - Expectations of popular - Disconfirmation related vote percentages to actual election outcome percandidate - Desired distribution of - Overall satisfaction with 100 points across results candidates - Beliefs about each - Satisfaction with results candidate on (a) foreign obtained by each candidate policy, (b) domestic economy, (c) other domestic issues, and (d) personal integrity - importance of the four issues listed above - Expectations re: - Perceived performance advertising effectiveness re: advertising effectiveness and unfair campaign - Expectations re: unfair - Disconfirmation re: ad. campaign effectiveness and unfair campaigns - Disconfirmation of overall process - Satisfaction with overall process 149 IV-2.1. Election Outcome Satisfaction Model - Operationalization of Key Constructs The complete EOSM is depicted in Figure 15. Construct operationalizations are presented here in the order in which they appear in the model, from left to right. A table summarizing these operationalizations, Table 16 appears at the end of this section. Expectations In Section II-3.l, the range of expectations measurements was described . and discussed. It was concluded that the most reasonable operationalization of expectations was "predictive expectations," that is, the level of performance actually anticipated by the respondent as measured before exposure to performance. Further, measurement of expectations appeared to be most consistent with its conceptualization when the evaluative nature of expectations was held to a minimum. Therefore for the election outcome model, expectations is operationalized as the percent of mpular votes each candidate is actually expected to receive on voting day. Several advantages result from measuring expectations in this manner. First, it guarantees that expectations are measured on exactly the same scale as is the ultimate objective performance of each candidate. Thus, direct and objective comparison of performance with a priori expectations of performance is possible. Second, expectations and desires are also measured on exactly the same "percentage" scale, enabling direct comparisons of expectations and desires. Third, it enhances the competitive dimension of the model by forcing explicit trade-offs among candidates in a zero-sum context (i.e., percentages must add to 100). 150 Desires As discussed in Section lI-3.2, desires has been infrequently included as a separate antecedent variable. As is true of expectations, desires is most useful when operationalized in terms of objective performance levels rather than evaluative performance levels. Therefore for the election outcome model, desires are operationalized a_s the percentage of votes (that is. the number of points out of 100) a subject would want to assign to each candidate on voting day. There are two major advantages to this operationalization of desires. First, as discussed above with regard to expectations, the measurement for desires is directly comparable with measures of both expectations and ultimate performance. No previously published study has included such directly comparable measures of these three constructs. Second, this operationalization of desires is unambiguous enough to allow responses of either the "more is better" or the "ideal point" variety (see Section II-3.2). Previously used scales left this distinction open to interpretation of both the subject and the researcher. One possible disadvantage of this operationalization is that it may not match the manner in which voters would normally conceptualize or express their desires in an election context. Specifically, some voters may simply desire that "Bush win" or that "Clinton win," and may not care by how much. A related potential problem is that someone may desire a candidate to receive 35% of the vote and win (in a three way race) while someone else may desire a candidate to receive 49% of the vote and lose. 151 The second of these potential problems is addressable, in part, through empirical analysis. In a three way race, it is clear that a candidate who receives 32% of the vote or less is a loser and a candidate who receives 51% or more of the vote is a winner. Between 32% and 51%, however, a candidate may be either a loser or a winner. To address this issue, respondents were also asked who they would vote for. The first potential problem, however, is less easily addressed. If someone only desires that someone win or lose, is that person constrained by the format of the measurement from adequately expressing his or her desires? The answer is "probably not" given the characteristics of the sample. The sample is generally well-educated and it is doubtful that a respondent would be unable to express his or her desires in the format requested. A more serious question may be whether the measurement format imposes an unrealistic level of exactness on the results. In other words, might someone desire only that Bush win, but, because of the format of the question, be forced to assign somewhere between 34 and 100 points to Bush thereby implying more finely- tuned desires than is actually felt? Although this may have occurred to some degree, there is no evidence from interviewers or from response rates to this specific question that any confusion existed. Further, because the analysis is focused on relationships rather than on means, it is unlikely this potential problem has major implications for the analysis proposed here. Though a respondent may have only desired that candidate A win, it is likely that they could rank order the three candidates in some sort of preference order; the assignment of points is a more detailed way of specifying the relative desires associated with each candidate. 152 Finally, the task of assigning 100 points to reflect desired candidate performance in this particular context seems especially appropriate given that the media presented polling results in a similar format (proportion of likely voters desiring each candidate) almost daily. Thus, in the context of a political election asking respondents to assign 100 points to reflect level of desire for each candidate appears to be a reasonable strategy. One potential drawback of the operationalization of both expectations and desires is the use of a single item scale to measure each. Although multiple item scales are generally perceived to be superior, it is difficult to imagine how items could be added to the measurement of both constructs which 1) were not simply a reworded version of the current item and 2) would not jeopardize the direct comparability of the two variables with each other and with actual parformance. Attitudes A subject's attitude towards a satisfaction target has been shown to be an antecedent of satisfaction processing (see Section II-3.3). Attitude is operationalized in a manner consistent with the Fishbein (1967) expectancy- value model, that is, as the summed cross products of beliefs (that the target possesses a specific characteristic) times the importance (of that characteristic) in a manner which is both context-specific and personalized. For the election outcome model, a similar belief times immrtance operationalization is used, incorporating the following four characteristics: domestic economy, other domestic issues, foreigp policy, and personal integrity. These four characteristics were consistently shown in public opinion polls to be salient candidate attributes. Likewise, media coverage of 153 the election seemed to focus on these candidate attributes. Beliefs were measured on a 10 point scale anchored by "will do an extremely poor job" (= 1) and "will do an extremely good job" (= 10). Importance of each attribute was measured on a 10 point scale anchored by "extremely a_nimportant" (= 1) and "extremely important" (= 10). Disconfirmation The concept of disconfirmation has been central to most of the empirical satisfaction literature since about 1980. Various attempts at conceptualizing and measuring disconfirmation are discussed in detail in Section II-3.5. The two major decisions to make regarding the operationalization of disconfirmation are 1) what standard should be used and 2) whether the measure should be subjective or derived. In order to make the measure of disconfirmation consistent with the measure of expectations, the standard disconfirmed is predictive expectations. Further, in this dissertation, the measurement of disconfirmation will be subjective rather than derived for two reasons. First, subjective measures appear to be the most consistently significant as antecedents of satisfaction, despite some theoretical shortcomings. Second, given that ultimate performance is objective, it is uniform across all subjects. Any derived measure would require the subtraction of expectations from a "constant" (actual performance), and thus would explain no variance in satisfaction in addition to the variance already explained by expectations. Thus, a derived measure would be completely meaningless in the model proposed here. Therefore, for the election outcome model disconfirmation is the subjectively expressed degree to which a candidate's actual performance was 154 worse (= 1) or better (= 7) than expected. This operationalization is most consistent with other subjective measures of disconfirmed predictive expectations. Satisfaction The broad range of satisfaction measures, from non-verbal symbolic scales through complex multiattribute summated scales, is reviewed in detail in Section II-2. Here, satisfaction is measured for the performance of each candidate and for the election outcome overall. In this dissertation satisfaction with Bush's performance, satisfaction with Clinton's performance, and overall satisfaction with the outcome of the election are each measured on identicai scales ranging from "extremely satisfied" (= 7) to "extremely dissatisfied" (= l). Variable Expectations Desires Attitudes Disconfirmation per Caiddate Overall Satisfaction Satisfaction with Carddate 155 Table 16 Wording Measured before the election Regardless of who you personally support, what do you think the outcome of the election will actually be? Please indicate the percent of the popular vote that you expect each candidate will actually get. Sippose for the moment that you codd distribute 100 points among the candidates instead of having just one vote. You can give all 100 to one cmdidate and zero to the others, or you can distribute the points any wayyouwish. Howmanypointswouldyou give to each candidate? Please evaluate the three candidates on (A) foreign policy, (8) the domestic eccnorny, (C) domestic issues excluding the economy, and (D) personal 'ntegrity....Give each candidate between 1 and 10 points. How important are the move sets of issues to you? Operationalization of Constructs -- Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Scale 0 through 100 toeechcanddate (summing to 100 across all cmddates) 0 through 100 toeachmnddate (summing to 100 across all cmddates) 1- 'Will do an extremely poor job“ though 10- 'Will do an extremely good job' 1 -" Extremely Unimportant' through 1 O-' Extremely Important“ (Note: the belief and importance measuernents for each attribute are multiplied then summed across all attributes to create a formative construct) Measured after the election Were the results better or worse than you expected? Note that whether your canddate woncrlost, hecouldhave donebetteror worse that you expected he would. The actual results of the election were: 3896 for Bush, 4396 for Clinton, and 1996 for Perot. How satisfied or dissatisfied are you with the results? Please mswer the same question for each of the candidates separately. 7-pt. semantic differential from " much worse than Iexpected' to " mudi better than Iexpected' 7-pt. semantic differential from 'extremeiy dissatisfied' to 'extremeiy satisfied' 7-pt. semantic differential from, 'extrernely dissatisfied“ to 'extremeiy satisfied“ 156 IV-2.2. Campaign Process Satisfaction Model - Operationalization of Key Constructs The complete CPSM is depicted in Figure 16. Again, construct operationalizations are presented in the order in which they appear in the model, from left to right. A table summarizing these operationalizations, Table 17 appears at the end of this section. Expectations A complete discussion of the range of expectations measurement appears in Section II-3.l. As in the EOSM, expectations is most reasonably operationalized as "predictive expectations." However, unlike the EOSM, measurement of expectations cannot utilize an "objective" scale as there is no widely understood and accepted means of measuring advertising effectiveness or campaign unfairness. Therefore. in t_hi_§ model, eapectations regarding each candidate's performance with regard to advertising effectiveness and running an unfair campaigp is measured on a "will definitely hapmn" (= 10) to "will definitely not happen" (= 1) scale. Perceived Performance Again, because there are no widely understood and accepted means of measuring advertising effectiveness and/or running an unfair campaign, perceived performance is measured in this model. To maintain comparability with the expectations measure, perceived performance is measured on similar scales. In this model, perceived performance with rem to both aavertisigg effectiveness and running an unfair campaign are measured on a scale anchored with "False-didn't ha en" = l to "True--ha ened a lot"(= 10). 157 Disconfirmation As in the EOSM, disconfirmation is measured as a subjective construct in which predictive expectations are the standard disconfirmed. Disconfirmation. therefore. is measured as the degree to which performance is Mged to be "more than expected" (= 10) or "less tLan expected" (= 1) for ear; of the two included process attributes. Overall Disconfirmation Since "overall process satisfaction" is the ultimate target of this model, an intervening, general measure of disconfirmation is included. This is necessary because the term "campaign process" could reasonably include a very large number of possible campaign attributes. Because only two of the possible campaign process attributes are considered in this model, an overall measure of disconfirmation is included so that other non—specified attributes salient to individual respondents (which may be more important than the two included attributes) can contribute to explaining variance in overall process satisfaction. Overall disconfirmation is measured on a seven point "much better than expected" (= 7) to "much worse than expected" (= 1) scale. Satisfaction The range of possible satisfaction measures and a discussion of satisfaction "targets" appears in Section 11.2. In the CPSM, satisfaction with the campaign process is measured. The scale used is identical to the seven point satisfaction scale used the EOSM, ranging from "extremely dissatisfied" (= l) to "extremely satisfied" (= 7). 158 Table 17 Operationalization of Constructs Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Variable Wording Scale Measured before the election Expectations Please indcate how you expect the election 1-"No, this will campaign will be conducted [asked for definitely not "advertising will be extremely effective" and happen" to "will run an unfair campaign" for 10-"Yes, this eachcanddate] will definitely happen" Measured after the election Perceived Performance We would like you to make two evaluations 1-"false (didn't each on a ten point scale. The first is an happen)" to evaluation of how true or false a statement 10-"true is....[asked for "advertising being extremely (happened a effective" and "running an unfair campaign" lot)" for each canddateJ Disconfirmation The second is an evaluation of whether some- 1-"less than 1 thing happened more or less that you expected expected" to it would. [asked for "advertising being 10-"more than extremely effective" and "running an unfair lexpected" campaign" for each candidate] Overall disconfirmation [Overall] Was the process better or worse 7-pt. semantic than you expected? differential from "rruch worse than lexpected" to "much better than I expected" Overall Satisfaction Overall, how satisfied or dissatisfied are you 7-pt. semantic with this year's presidential election differential from campaign process (i.e., the way the carmaigi "extremely was condicted)? dssatisfied" to "extremely satisfied" 159 IV-3. Other Relevant Variables In addition to the variable used in each of the models, other relevant variables were collected and used during data analysis. These variables are enumerated in Table 18. First, both level of certainty and level of involvement were thought to have the potential to compete with the independent variables of interest in the two models; collecting data on them would allow their effects to be controlled for, if needed. Choice Certainty Choice certainty was measured to determine whether Bush versus Clinton voters differed in the degree to which they were confident of their selection. This variable was collected because systematic differences in level of certainty could logically be related to amount of processing undertaken by certain respondent groups. Certainty was measured both before and after the election. Involvement Involvement was measured using a reduced version of Zaichowsky's (1985) involvement scale. It, too, was measured because differential levels of involvement might be expected to affect processing intensity. Political Affiliation and Demographics Political affiliation and demographic variables were collect for classification and comparison purposes. Interviewers were instructed to gather data from acquaintances which reflected the population of adult voters. 160 Collecting this information allowed comparisons to be made to the general electorate. In addition, political affiliation variables, including past voting behavior, were collected to determine the extend of "brand switching" which occurred among respondents. Operationalization of Constructs Other Relevant Variables Variable Certainty (before election) Certainty (after election) Involvement Political Affiliation Demographics 161 Table 18 Wording How certain are you of your choice? Putacheck markinoneoftheseven spaces to reflect how certa‘n you are. (asked after determining who subject would vote for " ....if the election were held tomorrow....') How certain were you of your choice? Put a check mark in one of the seven spaces to reflect how certain you were at the time you were voting. How do you feel about the coming presidential election? Please put a check mark in one of the seven spaces to reflect how you feel. (5 semantic differential scales) Are you a registered voter? Are you a registered Democrat? Are you a registered Republican? Did you vote in the last election? If so, for whom? Sex: Age Please check the highest level of emcation you atta'ned: Please check off your total family inccrne per year. By 'family' we mean 81 people related to you and living in your household. Scale 1 - Not at all certain to 7 - Extremely certain 1 - Not at all certain to 7 - Extremely certain 1 - unimportant to me - 7 - important to me 1 - irrelevant to me -- 7 - relevant to me 1 - uninteresting to me -- 7 - interesting to me 1 - bor'mg to me -- 7 - fascinating to me 1 - means nothing in my life- 7-meansalotinmylife Yes-No Yes-No Yes-No Yes - No Bush - Dukakis Male - Female ... years _less than high school _graduated from him school ..some college or post high school education _graduate from 41-year college (BA/BS or similar) -Master's level degree or equivdent _Ph.D. -under $5,000 -35,000 - $9,999 .310,000 - $14,999 .315,000 - $19,999 -320,000 - $24,999 _SZS.000 - $29,999 _S30,000 - 3 39,999 .340,000 - $49,999 .350,000 - $59,999 -Over $60,000 Chapter V Results This chapter is divided into six sections. The first section presents a general description of the Clinton and Bush voter subsamples used in the various two-group analyses. Sections two through five of this chapter each deal with a different analytical tool - subsample combination. The second and third sections each deal with one of the main hypothesized models (Election Outcome Satisfaction Model and the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model) comparing Clinton versus Bush voters. The fourth section presents results of an analysis of satisfied versus dissatisfied voters within the Election Outcome Satisfaction Model. The fifth section contains a correlation analysis of satisfied versus dissatisfied voters on variables collected for the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model. The sixth section summarizes research findings which specifically relate to the four research hypotheses. Within sections two through five of this chapter, results relating to the four research hypotheses are presented. Table 19 summarizes the research hypotheses and identifies which section contains results related to which research hypothesis. V-l. General Description of the Subsamples For each of the two models, a two-group analysis is performed. The two groups analyzed are Clinton supporters and voters versus Bush supporters and voters. "Supporters and voters" are defined as those who reported supporting a particular candidate pre-election and voting for that same candidate: those who supported and voted for Clinton are in the first group, and those who 162 Organization of Chapter 5--Sections Addressing Results Relating to Specific Research Hypotheses Research Hypotheses #1: Multiple targets of satisfaction are relevant to the overall satisfaction formation process. #2: Processes relevant to the formation of satisfaction with competing alternatives are structurally related (via cross-over effects). #3: Dissatisfied consumers process more extensively than do satisfied consumers. #4: Effects of desires will dominate the effects of expectations on the satisfation formation process in high involvement situations. 163 Table 1 9 Analytical Complete §ample EOSMl PSMZ Section Number.... V.Z.3 V.3.3 v.2.4 - - v2.5 - - V2.6 - - Tool Partial EOSM3 V.4.Z V.4.3 V.4.1 am le CPSM4 V.S 1) Clinton voters versus Bush voters in Z-grcup analysis 2) Clinton voters versus Bush voters in Z-group analysis 3) Satisfied Clinton voters versus Dissatisfied Bush voters in Z-group analysis 4) Satisfied Clinton voters versus Dissatisfied Bush voters in correlation analysis 164 supported and voted for Bush are in the second group. For convenience, these groups will be referred to as "Clinton voters" and "Bush voters" in the remainder of this dissertation. Note that those who supported one candidate before the election but voted for a different candidate are omitted from both groups (as are those who voted for Perot). Table 20 presents means of the variables for each group and significant differences between the groups on these variables. Differences between the groups with respect to variables used in each model are discussed in the relevant sections to follow. From Table 20, note especially the following: 1) There is some evidence of allegiance-switching prior to the pre- election measurement. First, over one fourth of Clinton voters (28.2%) voted for Bush in the previous election, though only 396 of Bush voters voted for Dukakis. Second, 14.796 of Bush voters are registered Democrats while 7.796 of Clinton voters are registered Republicans. 2) Voters for each candidate appear to be equally involved in the election as measured by all five involvement items: importance, relevance, interest, fascination, and meaning. 3) Voters for each candidate reported equal levels of certainty about their choice before the election, while Clinton voters reported slightly higher levels of certainty following the election. 4) There is no difference in the age of Clinton versus Bush voters in this sample; Clinton voters have received more education, and Bush voters reported higher household incomes. 5) In this sample, significantly more Bush voters versus Clinton voters are male (52.6% versus 29.5%). 165 Table 20 Description of the Sample Differences Between Clinton and Bush Subsamples on Selected Variables Significantly Clinton Bush Different? 19.9221 yams: -vaIue 2 Political packggound Percent registered Democrats 61.5 14.7 <.053 Percent registered Republicans 7.7 64.2 <.053 Voting pattern in 1988 election: a) voted for Bush 28.2 68.0 <.053 b) voted for Dukakis 38.5 3.1 <.053 c) rid not vote 33.3 29.9 - - lnv 1v t d ertain Relevance of the 1992 election4 (7 pt. scales): a) "important to me" 6.35 6.41 - - b) "relevant to me" 6.06 6.22 - - c) "interesting to me" 6.06 6.05 - - d) "fascinating to me" 5.55 5.33 - - e) "means a lot in my life" 5.71 5.75 - - Certainty of choice (7 pt. scales)5: a) before the election 6.14 6.18 - - b) after the election 6.32 6.00 .09 Other Characgeristics Demogaphics6 a) age 31.5 29.8 - - b) income category? 6.66 7.69 .03 c) education (96 college grad or higier) 69.2 50.5 <.053 d) gender (96 male) 29.5 52.6 <.OS3 (1) (2) (3) (4) Includes respondents who supported the cmdidate before the election and voted for the canddate. Using a difference of means t-test unless otherwise noted. Difference of proportions test. Opposite scale labels were " uninportant to me,‘ 'irrelevmt to me,“ 'minteresting to me,‘ “boring to me“ and 'meens nothing in my life.‘ Measurements taken before the election. (6) (5) (7) Demographic characteristics of all U.S. voters (source: New York Times November 5, 1992, p. 89) Clinton Votgs Bush Voters median age: 41.3 41.8 medan 'ncome: $35,024 $42,407 96 college graduate or higher. 40.3 41.6 gender (96 male): 43.2 46.7 Endpoints labeled 1 - ”not at all certain,‘ 7 - 'extremeiy certain." Categories: 1 - raider $5,000 6 - $25,000 - $29,999 2 - $5,000 - $9,999 7 - $30,000 - 3 39,999 3 - $10,000 - $14,999 8 - $40,000 - $49,999 4 - $15,000 - $19,999 9 - $50,000 - $59,999 5 - $20,000 - $24,999 10 - Over $60,000 166 V-2. Results of the Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Results of the two-group analysis using the Election Outcome Satisfaction Model (EOSM) are presented in this section. First, differences between the two groups with respect to the variables included in the model are highlighted. Then, results of the LISREL analysis are presented. Finally, results associated with each of the research hypotheses are described. V-2.1. Differences Between the Two Groups (EOSM) Although research questions specifically address the relationships between key variables, means and standard deviations of model variables are presented in Table 21 for completeness and to highlight differences between the groups. Note that Clinton and Bush voters differ significantly on all variables included in the model (for all differences, p-values < 0.001 for two-tailed difference of means t-tests, except as indicated). Specifically, Clinton voters expressed a higher level of desires, expectations and attitude for Clinton than did Bush voters, while Bush voters indicated higher levels than Clinton voters on these same variables with regard to Bush. Regarding Clinton's performance, Bush voters had a slightly higher level of disconfirmation (p = 0.124 for two-tailed t-test) than did Clinton voters. Regarding Bush's performance, Clinton voters indicated higher disconfirmation than did Bush voters. Finally, Clinton versus Bush voters expressed higher levels of satisfaction with Clinton's performance, Bush's performance, and the overall election results. 167 Table 21 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Means and Standard Deviations of Each Group Clinton Bush p-values Voters Voters from Mean Std. Dev. Mean M M1 For Clinton: Desires 76.179 18.910 11.381 14.576 0.000 Expectations 49.051 7.243 44.490 7.823 0.000 Attitudes 243.909 44.512 1 54.660 68.250 0.000 Disconfirmation 4.645 1.334 4.979 1.472 0.124 Satisfaction 5.705 1.250 1.794 1.020 0.000 For Bush: Desires 12.808 14.667 78.948 19.325 0.000 Expectations 37.676 6.340 42.552 9.055 0.000 Attitudes 178.779 56.104 266.221 63.918 0.000 Disconfirmation 4.263 1.237 2.854 1.179 0.000 Satisfaction 4.551 1.593 2.010 1.075 0.000 Overall: Satisfaction w/ election results 5.910 1 .1 86 1 .979 1.1 1 8 0.000 1 p-values for t-test for Ho: u1- ”2- 168 When groups are compared on the degree of pre-election desires with regard to "their candidate," a similar level is observed. That is, Clinton voters had a mean desire of 76.2 for Clinton while Bush voters had a mean desire of 78.9 for Bush (p value = .358). However, Bush voters had a more positive attitude towards Bush than Clinton voters had towards Clinton (p value =.008), and Bush voters had a poorer attitude towards Clinton than Clinton voters had towards Bush (p value = .012). The two groups differed on their expectations of the relative performance of each candidate: Clinton voters showed a difference of l 1.4 in the expected performance of Clinton over Bush, while Bush voters showed a spread of only 1.9 for Clinton over Bush. Because attitude towards each candidate is measured by combining the belief times importance of four candidate attributes, a separate table (Table 22) is presented to provide details of this variable. Again, note that the mean values of all importance component variables differ significantly between groups, as do the mean values of all belief component measures. While both groups give highest importance ratings for "domestic economy" and lowest ratings to "foreign policy," there are differences between the groups. Clinton voters rate "domestic economy" and "other domestic issues" as being more important than do Bush voters (p = .069 and p = .020, respectively). Bush voters give "foreign policy" and "personal integrity" higher importance ratings than do Clinton voters (p = .010 and p = .005, respectively). If the attributes are rank-ordered based on these importance ratings, "personal integrity" would rank above "other domestic issues" for Bush voters, while the reverse order would hold for Clinton voters. 169 Table 22 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Components of Attitude Towards the Candidate Significantly Clinton Bush Different? Voters1 Votersl -value 2 MW knportance to respondents. (10 pt. scales)3: a) foreign policy 7.10 7.88 .010 b) domestic economy 9.36 9.02 .069 c) other domestic issues 8.71 8.16 .020 d) personal integrity 7.85 8.62 .005 Belief Cornponmt Evaluation of candidate Clinton. (10 pt. scales)4: a) foreign policy 6.45 4.02 .000 b) domestic economy 8.06 5.27 .000 c) other domestic issues 7.77 5.23 .000 d) personal integrity 6.92 3.97 .000 Evaluation of candidate M. (10 pt. scales)4: a) foreign policy 7.55 9.05 .000 b) domestic economy 4.30 6.94 .000 c) other domestic issues 4.19 7.01 .000 d) personal integrity 6.16 8.40 .000 ( 1 ) lndudes respondents who reported supporting the candidate before the election and voted for the canddate. (2) Using a difference of means t-test with Ho: u1-u2. (3) Endpoints labeled 1 - 'extremeiy animportant' to 10 - 'extrernely important to me.“ (4) Endpoints labeled 1 - "wil do an extremely poorjob' to 10 - 'will do an extremely goodjob.‘ 170 V-2.2. Results of the EOSM Two-Group LISREL Analysis First, the correlation matrix for each group is presented. Then, overall and group-specific indicators of fit are provided. The top half of Table 23 contains the correlation matrix for Clinton voters. The bottom half of Table 23 presents results for Bush voters in a similar format. Covariance matrices were used as input for the analyses. Overall, the model fit the data moderately well. The appropriate fit index of the two group model overall is chi square goodness-of-fit. For EOSM, the chi square value is 75.60 with 46 degrees of freedom (p = .004). In addition, the comparative fit index (CFI) is .95. Within group indicators of fit are provided in Table 24. The goodness of fit (GFI) index for Clinton and Bush voters are .938 and .927, respectively. Squared multiple correlations for endogenous variables in the Clinton voter group range from .001 to .232, the total coefficient of determination of the structural equations is 0.127. These statistics are all higher for the Bush voter group: squared multiple correlations range from .024 to .415, and the total coefficient of determination for the structural equation is .330. There are two modification indices greater than five for the Clinton voter group and five for the Bush voter group. A total of five standardized residuals lie outside the -2.0 to 2.0 range for the Clinton voters, while eleven lie outside that range for the Bush voters. Although there are several standardized residuals outside the -2 to +2 range in each group, an examination of their distribution indicates they are roughly normally distributed (see Figure 17). Of the five high modification indices indicating the need for additional structural paths, four of the suggested paths lead directly to "overall Clinton Voters dd ”OOOVQU‘AMNd -0.194 -0.034 -0.234 0.1 51 0.091 -0.1 70 0.179 -0.1 39 0.244 Bush Voters dd ”OUOVOU'IéwN-l -0.231 -0.031 -0.026 0.130 -0.142 0.012 0.050 -0.001 0.105 0.375 0.324 0.260 0.075 0.1 70 0.1 78 -0.1 34 -0.Z30 -0.237 01¢de 171 Table 23 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Correlation Matrices 3 4 5 0.494 - - - - 0.376 0.329 0.177 0.209 -0.003 0.036 0.004 -0.083 0.092 0.020 0.262 -0.061 -0.078 -0.360 -0.096 0.008 0.087 0.075 0.057 -0.1 06 3 4 5 0.467 - - - - 0.617 0.477 0.355 0.303 0.353 0.085 0.062 0.049 0.405 0.440 0.442 -0.363 -0.432 -0.459 -0.333 -0.112 ~0.175 -0.207 -0.194 -0.343 En eno Variabl Clinton Disconfirmation Bush Disconfirmation Clinton Satisfaction Bush Satisfaction Overall Satisfaction 0.080 - - - - -0.093 0.333 - - - - 0.135 -0.1 13 -0.827 -0.200 -0.372 -0.027 0.508 -0.230 -0.518 0.198 - - - - 0.507 0.160 - - - - -0.282 -0.120 -0.786 -0.181 -0.623 -0.114 0.1 14 -0.056 -0.242 Exo e ous Var les Clinton Attitude Clinton Expectations Clinton Desires Bush Desires dd 0.105 0.519 0.224 0.446 -0.178 10 11 0.069 - - - - 172 Table 24 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Within Group Indicators of Fit Clinton Bush Voters Voters Goodness of Fit Index 0.938 0.927 Total Coefficient of Determination for the Structural Equations 0.127 0.330 Squared Multiple Correlations for: Clinton Disconfirmation 0.001 0.024 Bush Disconfirmation 0.073 0.064 Clinton Satisfaction 0.232 0.269 Bush Satisfaction 0.083 0.277 Overall Satisfaction 0.170 0.415 Modification lndices Over 5 twol fiveZ Standardized Residuals: less than -2 two3 six4 greater than 2 three5 five6 Root Mean Square Residual 2.851 4.729 1 Both of them are for structural paths: C. Desire -> Overall Sat. (5.007) and B. Desire -> Overall Sat. (9.948). 2 Three of them are for structural paflrs: B. Desire -> Overall Sat. (5.914), B. Expectation -> C. Sat. (12.049), and B. Attitude -> Overall Satisfaction (6.201 ). 3 They are: B. Disconfirmation - Overall Sat. (-2.023) and B. Desires - Overall Sat. (-3.225). 4 They are: 8. Disconfirmation - B. Attitude (-2.235), B. Desires - C. Sat. (-3.225), B. Expectations - C. Sat (-4.076), B. Attitude - 8. Sat. (-2.023), B. Desire - Overall Sat. (-3.27S), and B. Att - Overall Sat. (-3.080). 5 They are: 8. Attitude - C. Sat. (2.431), C. Attitude - 8. Sat. (2.452), and C. Desire - Overall Sat. (2.274). 6 They are: B. Desire - C. Disconfirmation (2.014), C. Desire - B. Disconfirmation (2.489), C. Desire - 8. Sat. (2.323), C. Attitude - Overall Sat. (2.123), C. Desire - Overal Sat. (2.815) 173 20-— - 184” - 16w ‘ Number of ._ . Residuals in each Category Bush Voter Group Magnitude of Standardized Residuals 20in ' 18" ' 16" ' 149- - Number of 12 " ' Residuals 10-- - in each Category C N l r I #051: 111 Clinton Voter Group ' Magnitude of Standardized Residuals Figure 17 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Distribution of Standardized Residuals 174 satisfaction" from antecedent variables. For Clinton voters, these paths are Clinton Desire to Overall Satisfaction (5.007) and Bush Desire to Overall Satisfaction (9.948). For Bush voters, these paths are Bush Desire to Overall Satisfaction (5.914) and Bush Attitude to Overall Satisfaction (6.201). Likewise, of the sixteen large standardized residuals, nearly half (seven) are associated with overall satisfaction. For Clinton voters, these paths are Bush Disconfirmation - Overall Satisfaction (-2.023), Bush Desire - Overall Satisfaction (—3.225), and Clinton Desire - Overall Satisfaction (2.274). For Bush voters, these paths are Bush Desire - Overall Satisfaction (-3.275), Bush Attitude - Overall Satisfaction (-3.080), Clinton Attitude - Overall Satisfaction (2.123), and Clinton Desire - Overall Satisfaction (2.815) . Of the remaining nine, seven are "cross-over paths," that is, the residuals are associated with antecedent variables of one candidate and post-election variables of the other candidate. For Clinton voters, these paths are Bush Attitude - Clinton Satisfaction (2.431) and Clinton Attitude - Bush Satisfaction (2.452). For Bush voters, these paths are Bush Desire - Clinton Satisfaction (-3.225), Bush Expectation - Clinton Satisfaction (-4.076), Bush Desire - Clinton Disconfirmation (2.014), Clinton Desire - Bush Disconfirmation (2.489), and Desire Clinton - Bush Satisfaction (2.323). V-2.3. EOSM Two-Group Results Related to Research Hypothesis #1 The test of the research hypothesis that multiple targets are relevant is very straight-forward. Paths from satisfaction with each candidate to overall satisfaction were hypothesized to be positive for both Clinton and Bush voters. Because path signs were hypothesized, all significance results reported in this section are for one-tail tests. 175 Table 25 contains unstandardized path estimates and their associated standard errors for Clinton versus Bush voters. Note that paths from satisfaction with each candidate to overall satisfaction are significant for both groups. For Clinton voters, the path estimate from Clinton Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction is .269 (significant at .05) and the path from Bush Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction is .141 (significant at .10). For Bush voters, the path estimate from Clinton Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction .554 and the path estimate from Bush Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction is .250 (both paths significant at the .01 level). The two paths of special interest are those which would pat be modeled in the traditional satisfaction model, namely Clinton Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction for Bush voters and Bush Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction for Clinton voters. Note that among Bush voters, the path from Clinton Satisfaction (i.e., the agr-choice) to Overall Satisfaction is of greater magnitude than the path from Bush satisfaction (i.e., the choice) to Overall Satisfaction. This difference was not hypothesized but is extremely interesting because it clearly demonstrates the importance of satisfaction formation processes relative to the non-choice among Bush voters. Among Clinton voters, there is no significant difference between the two paths. Thus, research hypothesis #1 is strongly supported by the EOSM two-group analysis, as the path from satisfaction with the non-choice is as important (Clinton voters) or more important (Bush voters) than is the path from satisfaction with the choice. It is possible to compare differences between Clinton voters and Bush voters in terms of the relative magnitudes of these paths. To make such a comparison, the common metric standardized paths must be compared (see 176 Table 25 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Unstandardized Estimates and Standard Errors of Structural Paths Clinton Voters Bush Voters Unstd. Std. Unstd. Std. Estimates Errors Estimates Errors Structural Path To Overall Satisfaction from: Clinton Satisfaction .269" * .1 16 .554" * * .098 Bush Satisfaction .141* .091 .250" * * .090 Clinton Disconfirmation —> Clinton Satisfaction 376* * * .095 .009 .066 Bush Satisfaction .297* * .132 .066 .070 Bush Disconfirmation —> Clinton Satisfaction -.101 .1 12 .288" * * .077 Bush Satisfaction .054 .1 58 .307’ * * .085 Clinton Desire -—> Clinton Disconfirmation -.001 .009 .006 .010 Clinton Satisfaction .008 .007 .017* * * .007 Clinton Expectation —> Clinton Disconfirmation -.005 .023 -.028* .019 Clinton Satisfaction .001 .018 -. 007 .012 Clinton Attitude —> Clinton Satisfaction .003 .003 .003“ .001 Bush Desire —-> Bush Disconfirmation .016* * .009 -.004 .006 Bush Satisfaction ‘ -.01 8 .014 -.024* * * .006 Bush Expectation —> Bush Disconfirmation -.040* " .021 -.031* * .014 Bush Satisfaction .025 .028 .014* .01 1 Bush Attitude —> Bush Satisfaction .003 .004 .001 .002 * Signifcant at .10 for 1-tail tests * * Significant at .05 for 1-tail tests * * * Significant at .01 for 1-tail tests 177 Table 26). The common metric standardized solution produces parameter estimates which have been standardized across the two groups so that direct comparisons of path magnitude are possible. First, the Clinton Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction path for Bush voters is of greater magnitude than the Clinton Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction path for Clinton voters (difference significant at .05 level, two tail test). Second, the Clinton Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction path for Bush voters is also significantly greater than the Bush Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction path for Clinton voters (difference significant at the .01 level, two tail test). Third, the path magnitudes related to each group's choice, i.e., Clinton Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction for Clinton voters and Bush Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction for Bush voters, are equal (difference not significant at .10 level, two tail test). Fourth, there is no difference between Clinton voters and Bush voters with regard to the magnitude of the path from Bush Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction. From this analysis, we can conclude that the single most important determinant of Overall Satisfaction is Clinton Satisfaction among Bush voters, i.e., satisfaction with a non-choice. Figure 18 and Figure 19 also present EOSM results. V-2.4. EOSM Two-Group Results Related to Research Hypothesis #2 To test the research hypothesis that cross-over effects connect the processes relating to both choice and non-choice, the information in Table 27 is once again examined. It was hypothesized that, in both groups, the cross- over effects would take the form of significant paths from disconfirmation with the choice to satisfaction with the non-choice, and from disconfirmation with the non-choice to satisfaction with the choice. 178 Table 26 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Common Metric Standardized Solution Path n.s.=nonsi nificant Clinton Satisfaction —>0veral| Satisfaction Bush Satisfaction —->Overall Satisfaction Clinton Disconfirmation —> Clinton Satisfaction Bush Satisfaction Bush Disconfirmation —> Clinton Satisfaction Bush Satisfaction Clinton Desires —> Clinton Disconfirmation Clinton Satisfaction Clinton Expectations --> Clinton Disconfirmation Clinton Satisfaction Clinton Attitude —> Clinton Satisfaction Bush Desires —-> Bush Disconfirmation Bush Satisfaction Bush Expectations —> Bush Disconfirmation Bush Satisfaction Bush Attitude —> Bush Satisfaction Clinton Voters .263 .165 .474 .314 -.109 n.s. .049 n.s. -.017 n.s. .116 n.s. -.024 n.s. .008 n.s. .170 n.s. .234 -.228 n.s. -. 260 .147 n.s. .119 n.s. Bush Voters .542 .293 .011 n.s. .070 n.s. .312 .278 .070 n.s. .255 -.149 -.050 n.s. .139 -.054 n.s. -.31 S -. 204 .086 .068 n.s. 179 Expectations Satisfaction w/ re: Clinton Clintons's Performance Clintons's Performance .263 (.116) Desires re: Clinton -.109 (112) Overall Satisfaction .314 (.132) -.2 : Desires re: 23‘ £014) .165 Bush (‘ 009) Disconfirmation ( . 09 1) ’ w/ Bush's Performance . 9 -.26 ‘ .031) (J 1 Satisfaction Expmtatioru .147 W/ Bush's re: Bush (.028) Performance .119 (.004) Attitude towards Bush Figure 18 Results: Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Clinton Voters The first nunber for each path is the common metric standardized solution parameter estimate, aid the second nunber is the associated standard error. Simifieent paths mpec in bold. 180 .139 (.001) + Expectations -.050 Satisfaction w/ re: Clinton | 0012) 011 Clintons's ' ' Performance 6019) ' confirmation w/ (.066) Clintons's 5“ .070 Performance (.090 .010 Desires re: ( ) . Clinton (-007) _312 (.017) Overall Satisfaction .070 (.070) Desires re: 3,, Disconfirrnaticn (.09 o) w/ Bush's Performance ‘78 (.08 ) Satisfaction w/ Bush's Performance Figure 19 Results: Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Bush Voters The first number for each path is the common metric standardized solution parameter estimate, aid the second number is the associated standard error. Significant paths appear in bold. 181 Among Clinton voters, the path from Clinton Disconfirmation to Bush Satisfaction (.297) is significant and positive as hypothesized (p < .05, one-tail test); while the path from Bush Disconfirmation to Clinton Satisfaction is negative as hypothesized, it is not of sufficient magnitude to be significant. Among Bush voters, the path from Bush Disconfirmation to Clinton Satisfaction (.288) is significant and positive (p < .01, one-tail test), as hypothesized; the path from Clinton Disconfirmation to Bush Satisfaction is neither significant nor negative. Thus. results from the EOSM provide moderate support for research hypothesis #2. ag cross-over effects are foun_d_ from disconfirmation with choice to satisfaction with non-choice for both groups. To compare differences in path magnitudes between the two groups, we again turn to the common metric standardized solution found in Table 26. Among Clinton voters, the path from Clinton Disconfirmation to Bush Satisfaction is .314, while among Bush voters, the path from Bush Disconfirmation to Clinton Satisfaction is .312. There is no difference in the magnitudes of these two paths. Thus, the cross-over effects appear to be of equal size for both groups. In addition to the cross-over effects evident in the structural paths, errors between Clinton Disconfirmation and Bush Disconfirmation, and between Clinton Satisfaction and Bush Satisfaction were allowed to covary. These error covariances, along with the error variances associated with the prediction of each of the endogenous variables is reported in the psi matrix results, Table 27. Note that the two covariances along with each of the variances are significant at the .01 level. 182 Table 27 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Psi Matrix Results Unstd. Std. Std. Estimate Error Estimate Psi Matrix Elements (1) (A) Clinton Supporters Clinton Disconfirmation 1.967' * " 0.217 0.986 Bush Disconfirmation 1369* " ' 0.151 0.932 Clinton Satisfaction 1.206' * * 0.199 0.961 Bush Satisfaction 2.348" " * 0.388 1.311 Overall Satisfaction 1.169‘ ' * 0.193 0.895 Disconfirmation: Clinton - Bush -0.443* * * 0.184 -0.259 Satisfaction: Clinton - Bush 0743‘ ' ‘ 0.215 0.496 (8) Bush Sumrters Clinton Disconfirmation 1.967' " * 0.217 0.986 Bush Disconfirmation 1.364' * * 0.151 0.932 Clinton Satisfaction 0.733" * * 0.108 0.584 Bush Satisfaction 0.849' " * 0.125 0.474 Overall Satisfaction 0.717* f " 0.106 0.549 Disconfirmation: Clinton - Bush -0.392* * 0.168 -0.229 Satisfaction: Clinton - Bush 0.221 * * * 0.086 0.148 (1) * Signifcant at .10 * * Significant at .05 * * * Significant at .01 All other psi matrix elements were set to zero in both groups. 183 V—2.5. EOSM Two-Group Results Related to Research Hypothesis # 3 Using results of the two group analysis of EOSM, it is possible to perform a weak test of research hypothesis #3, that dissatisfied people process more extensively than do satisfied people. A stronger test of research hypothesis #3 using EOSM and a subsample of voters is provided in Section V.4.3. As demonstrated in Table 21, Bush voters are less satisfied than Clinton voters on all three satisfaction measures. According to research hypothesis #3, then, one would expect to observe evidence of more extensive processing among Bush voters relative to Clinton voters. The results presented here are a "weak" test of the hypothesis because the samples are confounded: some Clinton voters were not satisfied and some Bush voters were not dissatisfied. In this analysis, amount of processing is indicated by the number of significant paths connecting variables measured pre-election and variables measured post-election (hereafter called "pre-post" paths) in the EOSM two—group analysis. From Table 25, we see that two such pre-post paths are significant for Clinton voters: Bush Desire to Bush Disconfirmation and Bush Expectation to Bush Disconfirmation. Both paths are significant at the .05 level (one-tail test). On the other hand, six pre-post paths are significant for Bush voters: Clinton Desire to Clinton Satisfaction, Clinton Expectation to Clinton Disconfirmation, Clinton Attitude to Clinton Satisfaction, Bush Desire to Bush Satisfaction, Bush Expectation to Bush Disconfirmation, and Bush Expectation to Bush Satisfaction. We conclude that Bush voters did exhibit more extensive processing than did Clinton voters. Therefore, research hypothesis #3 is supported. 184 One additional observation is that throughout Table 25, Bush voters in the sample exhibited smaller standard deviations for all but two of the paths than did Clinton voters in the sample. The two exceptions are the Clinton Desire to Clinton Satisfaction path for which the standard errors are equal, and the Clinton Desire to Clinton Disconfirmation path for which Clinton voters had a standard error of .009 while Bush voters had a standard error of .010. V-2.6. EOSM Two-Group Results Related to Research Hypothesis #4 Finally, to address the issue raised by research hypothesis #4, the relative impact of desires versus expectations on satisfaction, Table 28 is presented. It shows the total direct and indirect effects of expectations and desires on satisfaction with each candidate and on overall satisfaction. We see that only one expectations - endogenous variable path has significant total effects (Bush Expectation to Clinton Satisfaction). However, four desires - endogenous variable paths have significant total effects: Clinton Desire to Clinton Satisfaction and to Overall Satisfaction, and Bush Desire to Bush Satisfaction and to Overall Satisfaction. Therefore. research hypothesis #4 is supported. Parenthetically, it is worth noting that all five of the significant paths from expectations or desires to endogenous variables occurred among Bush voters (while none occurred among Clinton voters). This is further evidence in support of research hypothesis #3, that dissatisfied people process more extensively than do satisfied people. 185 Table 28 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Total Effects of Expectations versus Desires Clinton Voters Bush Voters Total Std. Total Std. Effects Errors Effects Errors For Clinton Expectation ———> Clinton Satisfaction -.003 .020 -.008 .018 Bush Satisfaction -.001 .001 -.002 .004 Overall Satisfaction -.001 .006 -.005 .010 Desire —-—> Clinton Satisfaction .007 .008 .017*** .007 Bush Satisfaction .000 .003 .000 .001 Overall Satisfaction .002 .002 .010"** .004 For Bush Expectation —> Clinton Satisfaction .004 .005 -.009* .007 Bush Satisfaction .023 .027 .005 .028 Overall Satisfaction .004 .005 .004 .009 Desire ——-> Clinton Satisfaction -.002 .002 -.001 .003 Bush Satisfaction -.017 .014 -.025*" .015 Overall Satisfaction -.003 .003 -.007*" .005 * Signifcant at .10 for 1-tail tests * * Significant at .05 for 1-tail tests * * * Significant at .01 for 1-tail tests 186 V-2.7. Summary of EOSM Results To summarize, the EOSM appears to fit the data relatively well overall. In the Clinton voter group, there were fewer high modification indices or standardized residuals than in the Bush voter group. However, for the Bush voter group, the proportion of variance explained for each of the endogenous variables was greater than in the Clinton voter group. Most of the large modification indices and standardized residuals could have been eliminated had direct structural paths between antecedent variables and overall satisfaction been specified. All four research hypotheses were supported to varying degrees. Strong support was found for research hypothesis #1, that multiple targets of satisfaction are relevant in the overall satisfaction formation process. Moderate support was found for research hypothesis #2, that the processing paths associated with each target are structurally related via cross-over paths. Moderate support was found for research hypothesis #3, that dissatisfied voters process more extensively than do satisfied voters. Finally, strong support was found for research hypothesis #4, that desires have greater total effects on satisfaction formation than do expectations. V-3. Results of the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Results of the two-group analysis using the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model (CPSM) are presented in this section. First, differences between the two groups with respect to the variables included in the model are highlighted. Then, results of the LISREL analysis are presented. Next, results associated with research hypothesis #1 are described. Finally, additional observations about the model results are presented. 187 V-3.l. Differences Between the Two Groups (CPSM) Although research questions specifically address the relationships between key variables, means and standard deviations of model variables are presented in Table 29 for completeness and to highlight differences between the groups. Note that Clinton and Bush voters differ significantly on most variables included in the model. Clinton and Bush voters had similar expectations regarding Clinton's running an unfair campaign, and both groups made similar disconfirmation judgments regarding Clinton's performance on both campaign elements. The two groups differed on all measures regarding Bush's campaign except on the perceived performance of Bush's advertising effectiveness. V-3.2. Results of the CPSM Two-Group LISREL Analysis This section contains results of the Campaign Process Satisfaction Model (CPSM) two-group LISREL analysis. First, the correlation matrix for each group is presented. Then, overall and group-specific indicators of fit are provided. The first half of Table 30 contains the CPSM correlation matrix for Clinton voters. Note that levels of significance appear below the correlations. The second half of Table 30 presents results for Bush voters in a similar format. Overall, the model fit is acceptable. The appropriate overall fit index is chi square goodness-of-fit statistic. For this model, the chi square value was 117.63 with 72 degrees of freedom (p = .001) 188 Table 29 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Means and Standard Deviations of Each Group Clinton Bush p-values Voters Voters from Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. t-testsl For ClintonZ: Expectations: ad. effectiveness 7.20 1.67 . 6.49 1.80 .010 Performance: ad. effectiveness 7.01 2.11 6.27 2.03 .020 Disconfirmation: ad. effectiveness 6.29 2.09 6.18 2.02 .707 Expectations: unfair campaign 4.70 2.26 5.26 2.65 .141 Performance: unfair campaign 3.84 2.38 4.63 2.96 .054 Disconfirmation: unfair campaign 4.55 2.17 4.61 2.20 .854 For Bush: Expectations: ad. effectiveness 5.55 2.02 6.53 1.84 .001 Performance: ad. effectiveness 4.26 2.33 4.69 2.20 .212 Disconfirmation: ad. effectiveness 4.17 2.06 3.54 1.96 .042 Expectations: unfair campaim 6.18 2.50 3.16 2.12 .000 Performance: unfair campaign 6.08 2.63 2.84 2.29 .000 Disconfirmation: unfair campaign 5.50 2.70 4.36 2.67 .000 Overall3: Disconfirmation: overall process 4.50 1.43 3.68 1.33 .000 Satisfaction: overall process 5.80 1.63 . 3.40 1.62 .001 1 p-values for t-test for Ho: u1- ”2- 2 10-p0int scales. 3 7-point scales. 189 Table 30 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Correlation Matrices Clinton Voters 1 2 10 11 12 13 14 1.000 -0.203 1.000 (0.079) 0.046 0.276 1.000 (0.691) (0.016) 0.093 0.224 0.069 1.000 (0.426) (0.053) (0.553) 0.302 ~0.269 0.086 -0.375 1.000 (0.007) (0.019) (0.454) (0.001) 0.076 -0.142 -0.061 -0.494 0.615 1.000 (0.508) (0.220) (0.595) (0.000) (0.000) 0.004 0.122 0.070 -0.005 0.281 0.374 1.000 (0.973) (0.302) (0.547) (0.969) (0.014) (0.001) 0.461 -0.062 -0.003 0.028 0.093 0.248 0.303 1.000 (0.000) (0.592) (0.976) (0.812) (0.421) (0.029) (0.008) 0.017 0.369 0.043 0.266 -0.200 -0.415 0.122 -0.161 1.000 (0.885) (0.001) (0.710) (0.022) (0.083) (0.000) (0.295) (0.164) -0.198 0.587 -0.006 0.130 -0.252 -0.270 0.062 -0.294 0.468 1.000 (0.087) (0.000) (0.958) (0.263) (0.028) (0.018) (0.601) (0.010) (0.000) -0.308 0.027 0.215 -0.064 0.012 -0.082 0.386 -0.060 0.180 0.009 1.000 (0.007) (0.821) (0.062) (0.590) (0.920) (0.483) (0.001) (0.605) (0.119) (0.937) -0.200 0.235 0.442 -0.075 -0.093 -0.069 0.090 0.134 -0.034 0.087 0.348 1.000 (0.080) (0.041) (0.000) (0.520) (0.416) (0.546) (0.439) (0.243) (0.770) (0.453) (0.002) 0.234 0.052 0.009 0.155 0.023 -0.116 0.157 0.081 0.506 0.164 -0.161 -0.076 1.000 (0.042) (0.659) (0.940) (0.187) (0.844) (0.317) (0.175) (0.489) (0.000) (0.116) (0.165) (0.501) -0.056 0.350 0.116 0.644 -0.322 ~0.290 0.083 0.028 0.259 0.258 -0.086 0.102 0.318 1.000 (0.626) (0.002) (0.316) (0.000) (0.004) (0.011) (0.482) (0.809) (0.025) (0.024) (0.462) (0.379) (0.005) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 0 1 1 1 2 1 3 1 4 W Wrinkles 1 Dbconfimtlon re: Chton Advertbhg Effectiveness 7 Expectation rs: Cliton Ad. Effectivursss 2 Disconfirnstion rs: Chton Unfas Canpsbnhg 8 Performance re: Chton Ad. Effectiveness 3 Disconfirmation rs: Bush Advertlshg Effectiveness 9 Expectation re: Chton Unfair Campaignhg 4 Disconftmation re: Bush Unfair Canpsignirg 10 Performance re: Cirton Unfas Cannabnhg 5 Overal Disconfirmation 11 Expectation rs: Bush Ad. Effectivenes 6 Overal Satisfaction with Certain Process 12 Performance re: Bush Ad. Effectivensu 13 Expectation rs: Bush Unfa's Canvabnhg 14 Performnce rs: Bush Unfak Carmalgnhg Bush 11 12 13 14 190 Table 30, continued Voters 1300 -0.062 1.000 (05531 -0.033 0.115 1.000 (0.753) (0.266) -0.061 0.259 0.080 1.000 (0.558) (0.011) (0.443) -0.113 -0.132 0.112 -0.051 1.000 (0.272) (0.200) (0.277) (0.623) -0.077 -0.117 -0.012 -0.021 0.708 1.000 (0.454) (0.255) (0.907) (0.843) (0.000) 0.070 0.036 -0.151 0.114 0.239 0.227 1.000 (0.496) (0.725) (0.143) (0.270) (0.018) (0.026) 0.567 0.062 -0.133 -0.005 -0.102 -0.038 0.149 1.000 (0.000) (0.549) (0.197) (0.965) (0.323) (0.715) (0.149) -0.057 0.219 -0.090 0.141 -0.014 -0.152 -0.110 0.135 1.000 (0.584) (0.034) (0.387) (0.175) (0.894) (0.141) (0.289) (0.193) -0.007 0.351 -0.055 0.263 -0.200 -0.250 -0.065 0.147 0.497 1.000 (0.949) (0.001) (0.596) (0.010) (0.054) (0.014) (0.529) (0.152) (0.000) 0.209 0.081 -0.015 0.002 -0.045 0.085 0.348 0.301 0.097 0.115 1.000 (0.041) (0.432) (0.884) (0.985) (0.659) (0.405) (0.001) (0.003) (0.349) (0.263) 0.112 0.082 0.444 0.181 0.061 0.146 0.086 0.076 -0.079 0.033 0.211 1.000 (0.275) (0.432) (0.000) (0.079) (0.555) (0.156) (0.406) (0.463) (0.450) (0.749) (0.039) -0.041 0.048 -0.117 0.274 0.096 -0.017 -0.003 0.049 0.302 0.166 -0.165 -0.264 1.000 (0.698) (0.643) (0.263) (0.008) (0.356) (0.871) (0.980) (0.642) (0.003) (0.108) (0.111) (0.010) -0.119 0.144 0.087 0.531 0.051 -0.004 0.007 -0.125 0.114 0.408 -0.021 0.006 0.389 1.000 (0.247) (0.162) (0.398) (0.000) (0.622) (0.966) (0.943) (0.224) (0.273) (0.000) (0.937) (0.952) (0.000) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1 0 1 1 1 2 1 3 14 W transmissible: 1 Disconfirmtion re: Chton Advertissrg Effectiveness 7 Expectation rs:CI1tor1 Ad. Effectiveness 2 Disconfirnation rs: Chton Unfak Cambnhg 8 Performance re: Clinton Ad. Effectiveness 3 Disconfimation re: 8M Advertlshg Effectiveness 9 Expectation re: Chton Unfa‘r Canvaignhg 4 Disconfirmation re: Bush Unfai Cannabnhg 10 Performance rs: Chton Unfai Cambnhg 5 Overal Disconfimation 11 Expectation re: Bush Ad. Effectivenes 6 Overal Satisfaction with Canvabn Process 12 Performance re: Bush Ad. Effectiveness 13 Expectation rs: Bush Unfak Canneignhg 14 Performance re: Bush Unfas Carmslgnhg 191 Group specific indicators of fit are provided in Table 31. The goodness of fit (GFI) index for Clinton and Bush voters are .893 and .945, respectively. Squared multiple correlations for endogenous variables in' the Clinton voter group range from .224 to .531, and the total coefficient of determination of the structural equations is 0.866. In general, these statistics are slightly lower for the Bush voter group: squared multiple correlations range from .049 to .546, and the total coefficient of determination for the structural equation is .697. There are six modification indices greater than five for the Clinton voter group and two for the Bush voter group. A total of eleven standardized residuals lie outside the -2.0 to 2.0 range for the Clinton voters, while seven lie outside that range for the Bush voters. Although there are several standardized residuals outside the "acceptable" range in each group, an examination of their distribution indicates they are roughly normally distributed, with the exception of one outlier for the Clinton group (see Figure 20). The outlying residual and the large number of high modification indices and residuals indicate that the model may be misspecified for the Clinton group. V-3.3. CPSM Two-Group Results Related to Research Hypothesis #1 The research hypothesis that multiple targets are relevant to the formation of overall satisfaction may be tested by examining the significant paths in the satisfaction formation process for Clinton and Bush voters. Of particular interest is the number of significant paths relating to candidate Bush among Clinton voters and relating to candidate Clinton among Bush voters. These are paths which would not be modeled in traditional satisfaction models. 192 Table 31 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Within Group Indicators of Fit Goodness of Fit Index Total Coefficient of Determination for the Structural Equations Squared Multiple Correlations for: Disconfirmation: Clin. Ad. Effectiveness Disconfirmation: Clin. Unfair Campaign Disconfirmation: Bush Ad. Effectiveness Disconfirmation: Bush Unfair Campaign Overall Process Disconfirmation Overall Process Satisfaction Modification lndices Over 5 Standardized Residuals: less than -2 greater than 2 Root Mean Square Residual Clinton Bush Voters Voters 0.893 0.945 0.866 0.697 0.262 0.326 0.354 0.119 0.224 0.215 0.419 0.292 0.291 0.049 0.531 0.546 sixl twoz six3 three4 five5 fourG 0.367 0.230 1 Five were for structural paths: BADDIS -> CADDIS (5.780), BUCDIS -> PROCSAT (12.372), PROCSAT ->BUCDIS (9.736), CADEX -> OVERDIS (9.114), and BADEX -> CADDIS (6.602). (”N They were: CADEX -> OVERDIS (7.637) and BADPER -> BUCDIS (5.069). They were: CADDIS - BADDIS (-3.421), CADDIS - BUCDIS (-3.938), CADDIS - PROCSAT (-3.748), CADDIS - BADEX (-2.206), CADDIS - BADPER (-2.209), and BUCDIS - PROCSAT (-1 2.022). (ll-b OVERDIS - CADEX (2.600), PROCSAT - CADEX (2.564). a) PROCSAT - BUCEX (2.488). ABREVIATIGNIS: CADEX Expectation re: Clinton Ad. Effectiveness BADEX CADPER Performance rs: Clinton Ad. Effectiveness BADPER CADDIS Disconfirmtion re: Clinton Ad. Effectivensss BADDIS CUCEX Expectation re: Clinton Unfair Campaign CUCPER Performs re: Clinton Unfair Corrosion BIKZEX CUCPER CUCOIS Disconfirrmtion re: Clinton Unfair Carrpaign BUCDIS They were: CADDIS - BADDIS (-5.412), BADDIS - PROCSAT (-3.065), and PROCSAT - CUCPER (-3.288). They were: CUCDIS - BUCDIS (4.393), CUCDIS - PROCSAT (3.446), OVERDIS - PROCSAT (2.569), They were: BADDIS - BUCDIS (3.124), OVERDIS - CADEX (2.374), PROCSAT - CADEX (3.950), Expectation re: 81-h Ad. Effectiveness Perforrnancs rs: Bush Ad. Effectiveness Disconfirmation rs: Bmh Ad. Effectiveness Expectation rs: Bush Unfair Carrpaign Performance re: Bah Unfair Carmaign Disconfirmation re: Bush Unfair Campaign OVERDIS Overall Disconflrrr-tion rs: overall process PROCSAT Overall Process Satisfaction 193 Clinton Voter Group 30-- - 27-— - 24L - 21 «i- - Number of 18.- . Residuals in each Category 12" ‘ \\\\\\\ \\\\\\\‘ -40r '31!) -2to '1“) a9” Oto 1w Zto 3m 4or less -3.9 -2.9 -1.9 0 .9 1.9 2.9 3.9 greater Magnitude of Standardized Residuals* *NOTE: Value of residual in '-4 or less' category is -1 2.02. Bush Voter Group 30-- ' 27+ - 244k - Number of 21 Residuals 18* ' in each ‘5“ ' Category 124- ~ 9r - . \ a -40r -3to -2to -lto -.9to Ono 1to 2m 3to 4or less -3.9 -2.9 -l .9 0 .9 1 .9 2.9 3.9 greater Magnitude of Standardized Residuals Figure 20 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Distribution of Residuals 194 Table 32 contains unstandardized path estimates and their associated standard errors for Clinton versus Bush voters. Error variances associated with the prediction of each of the endogenous variables is reported in Table 33. In addition, errors were expected to covary among the disconfirmation measures associated with each of the campaign elements. Therefore, the values of these covariances are also included in the table. Note that all the variances in both groups are significant at the .01 level, while 4 of the covariances among Clinton voters and 1 among Bush voters are significant. Among Clinton voters, two paths from antecedent variables regarding Bush have a direct effect on Overall Satisfaction with the campaign process: Expectations of Bush's Advertising (p < .01, one tail test) and Bush's Unfair Campaign Performance (p < .10, one tail test). Further, among Clinton voters, both paths from disconfirmation regarding Bush's campaign performance have direct effects on overall disconfirmation: Bush Advertising Disconfirmation (p < .10, one tail test) and Bush Unfair Campaign Disconfirmation (p < .01, one tail test). Thus, four of six potential paths to overall measures from Bush-related measures are significant for Clinton voters. Among Bush voters, one path from an antecedent variable regarding Clinton has a direct impact on Overall Satisfaction: Expectations of Clinton's Unfair Campaign (p < .10, one tail test). In addition, the path from Disconfirmation of Clinton's Unfair Campaign to Overall Disconfirmation is significant (p < .10, one tail test). Therefore, two of six potential paths to overall measures from Clinton-related measures are significant for Bush voters. We conclude that research hxmthesis #1 receives strong supmrt from the CPSM analysis among Clinton voters, and moderate support among Bush voters. 195 Table 32 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Unstandardized Estimates and Standard Errors of Structural Paths Clinton Voters Bush Voters Unstd. Std. Unstd. Std. Estimates Errors Estimates Errors Structural Path To Overall Satisfaction from: Overall Disconfirmation .468*** .093 .847*** .086 Expectation: C. Ad. Effectiveness .363‘” .091 -.007 .069 Performance: C. Ad. Effectiveness .033 .070 .018 .062 Expectation: C. Unfair Campaign -.206*** .077 -.069" .054 Performance: C. Unfair Campaign -.005 .065 -.045 .050 Expectation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness -.155* * .082 .104" .073 Performance: 8. Ad. Effectiveness -.002 .061 .052 .056 Expectation: B. Unfair Campaign -.022 .064 -.003 .067 Performance: 8. Unfair Campaign -.075* .054 .009 .062 To Overgfl Disconfirmation from: Disconfirmation: C. Ad. Effectiveness .204*** .072 -.079 .068 Disconfirmation: C. Unfair Campaign -.111* .070 -.089* .065 Disconfirmation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness .101" .072 .086 .070 Disconfirmation: B. Unfair Campaign -.200*"* .053 -.018 .062 To Disconfirmation: C. Ad. Effectiveness from: Expectation: C. Ad. Effectiveness -.155 .124 -.005 .097 Performance: C. Ad. Effectiveness 542*“ .098 .570*** .087 To Disconfirmation: C. Unfair Campaign from: Expectation: C. Unfair Campaign .140" .095 .027 .091 Performance: C. Unfair Campaign .47?” .091 242*“ .081 To Disconfirmation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness from: Expectation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness .153" .106 -.128* .101 Performance: 8. Ad. Effectiveness 362*” .091 .423*** .084 To Disconfirmation: B. Unfair Campaign from: Expectation: B. Unfair Campaign -.110 .101 .080 .101 Performance: 8. Unfair Campaign .696"** .096 .502*** .093 * Signifmnt at .10 for l-tail tests * * Significant at .05 for l-tali tests * * * Significant at .01 for 1-tail tests 196 Table 33 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Psi Matrix Results Unstd. Std. Std. Estimate Error Estimate Psi Matrix Elements (1) (A) Clinton Voters Disconfirmation: C. Ad. Effectiveness 3.358'” 0.558 0.782 Disconfirmation: C. Unfair Campaign 3.098' * ' 0.515 0.647 Disconfirmation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness 3.421‘ * ' 0.568 0.834 Disconfirmation: B. Unfair Campaign 4300' ' ' 0.716 0.699 Overall Disconfirmation 1.451 * " ' 0.241 0.764 Overall Satisfaction 1.123‘ * * 0.187 0.445 C. Ad. Effect. - C. Unfair Camp. -0.679* ' 0.387 -0.150 C. Ad. Effect. - 8. Ad. Effect. 0.852" * 0.411 0.203 C. Ad. Effect. - 8. Unfair Camp. 0794' * 0.456 0.154 C. Unfair Camp.- 8. Ad. Effect. 0.890* ' " 0.396 0.201 C. Unfair Camp.- 8. Unfair Camp -0.118 0.429 -0.022 8. Ad. Effect. - B. Unfair Camp. 0.319 0.452 0.064 (8) Bu_sh Voteg Disconfirmation: C. Ad. Effectiveness 2.755* * ' 0.409 0.642 Disconfirmation: C. Unfair Campaign 4222" ' * 0.628 0.881 Disconfirmation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness 3.029’ " 0.450 0.738 Disconfirmation: 8. Unfair Campaign 3.653’ * * 0.543 0.593 Overall Disconfirmation 1.695‘ * * 0.252 0.892 Overall Satisfaction 1.193' ' * 0.177 0.473 C. Ad. Effect. - C. Unfair Camp. -0.270 0.360 -0.059 C. Ad. Effect. - 8. Ad. Effect. 0.057 0.304 0.013 C. Ad. Effect. - B. Unfair Camp. -0.128 0.334 -0.025 C. Unfair Camp.- 8. Ad. Effect. 0.448 0.379 0.101 C. Unfair Camp.- 8. Unfair Camp 0823* * 0.422 0.151 8. Ad. Effect. - 8. Unfair Camp. -0.199 0.350 -0.040 (1 ) All other psi matrix eiernents were set to zero in both groups. * Signifcant at .10 * * Significant at .05 * * * Significant at .01 101' the C11] all< prc Cli V0 of f0- A. CG C211 197 Not only are more paths to overall satisfaction significant for Clinton voters than for Bush voters, for those paths which are significant in each of the two groups, the absolute value of each significant coefficient is larger for Clinton versus Bush voters. The common metric standardized solution, allowing for direct comparison of path magnitudes between the two groups, is provided in Table 34, Figure 21, and Figure 22. The path from Expectations of Clinton's Unfair Campaign to Overall Satisfaction has a common metric solution value of -.323 among Clinton voters versus a value of -.108 for Bush voters (significant difference at p < .01, 2-tail test). The path from Expectations of Bush's Advertising to Overall Satisfaction is -.188 for Clinton voters and .126 for Bush voters (significant difference at p < .01, 2-tail test). In addition, when the expectations - overall satisfaction link is compared for each of the campaign elements in terms of choice versus non- choice candidates, Clinton voters had larger path coefficients in all three of the cases for which differences were significant. For Expectations of Advertising Effectiveness of choice candidate, Clinton voters had a common metric standardized path estimate of .399 with regard to Clinton while Bush voters had a path of .126 with regard to Bush. (significant difference at p < .01, 2-tail test). For Expectations of Unfair Campaign by choice, Clinton voters had a path coefficient of -.323 for Clinton while Bush voters had a path coefficient of -.004 (significant difference at p < .01). With regard to Expectation of Advertising Effectiveness for the non-choice, Clinton voters had a path coefficient of -.188 while Bush voters had a path coefficient of -.088 (significant difference at p < .05, 2-tail test). Expectations regarding unfair campaign are equal for the two groups. I‘P T. To 198 Table 34 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Common Metric Standardized Solution Clinton Voters Bush Voters Path n.s.=nonsi nificant To Overall Satisfaction from: Overall Disconfirmation .406*** .735**" Expectation: C. Ad. Effectiveness 399*” -.008 Performance: C. Ad. Effectiveness .042 .023 Expectation: C. Unfair Campaign -.323*** -.108* Performance: C. Unfair Campaign -.008 -.077 Expectation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness -.188* * .126* Performance: 8. Ad. Effectiveness -.003 .074 Expectation: 8. Unfair Campaign -.032 -.004 Performance: 8. Unfair Campaign -.116* .014 To Overall Disconfirmation from: Disconfirmation: C. Ad. Effectiveness .306*** -.119 Disconfirmation: C. Unfair Campaign -.177* -.141* Disconfirmation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness .149* .127 Disconfirmation: B. Unfair Campaign -.361*** -.032 To Disconfirmation: C. Ad. Effectiveness from: Expectation: C. Ad. Effectiveness .131 -.004 Performance: C. Ad. Effectiveness .540*** .568*** To Disconfirmation: C. Unfair Campaign from: Expectation: C. Unfair Campaign .160* .030 Performance: C. Unfair Campaign .S86*** 300*” To Disconfirmation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness from: Expectation: 8. Ad. Effectiveness .145* -.121* Performance: 8. Ad. Effectiveness .403*** .474*** To Disconfirmation: B. Unfair Campaign from: Expectation: B. Unfair Campaign -.101 .074 Performance: 8. Unfair Campaign .687*** .495”* * Signifcmt at .10 for l-tall tests * ' Significant at .05 for 1-tail tests * * ' Significant at .01 for l-tail tests 199 .399 (.091) Figure 21 Results: Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Clinton Voters The first number for each path is the common metric standardized solution parameter estimate, and the second number is the associated standard error. Significant paths appear in bold. 200 ..008 (.069) .023 ( 062) < 668) Expecteu'on: . .191 ( 054) ..1 4 1 (.065) -.077 (.055')\ Overall Overall Satisfaction Disconfirmation .oa‘ “them” Figure 22 Results: Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Bush Voters The first number for each path is the common metric standardized solution parameter estimate, and the second number is the associated standard error. Significant paths appear in bold. 201 Further, among Clinton voters, there are significant paths from Bush Advertising Performance to Bush's Advertising Disconfirmation (p < .01), from Bush's Unfair Campaign Performance to Bush's Unfair Campaign Disconfirmation (p < .01) and from Bush's Expectation Advertising to Bush's Advertising Disconfirmation (p < .10). Among Bush voters, there are significant paths from Clinton Advertising Performance to Clinton's Advertising Disconfirmation (p < .001) and Clinton's Unfair Campaign Performance to Clinton's Unfair Campaign Disconfirmation (p < .001). Ihpg paths provide additional support for research hypothesis #1 by illustrating that each group processes antecedents related to their non-choice with respect to specific campaign elements. V-3.4. Additional Observations from the CPSM Two-Group Analysis In addition to results provided to test research hypothesis #1, the CPSM yielded two results not related to any research hypothesis but which are interesting because they are incongruent with previous satisfaction research findings: 1) The performance - satisfaction path is significant only for Clinton voters and only with regard to Bush's performance with respect to running an unfair campaign. The remaining seven possible performance - satisfaction paths are not significant. This finding is especially surprising given the strong support in the literature for the performance - satisfaction relationship. 2) For Clinton voters, the expectation - disconfirmation path for candidate Clinton is significant and positive with regard to unfair campaigns. The expectation - disconfirmation path for Bush's advertising effectiveness is 202 positive for Clinton voters. These findings are surprising because positive relationships between expectation and disconfirmation are uncommon empirically and are counter-intuitive. The positive relationship indicates that as expectations rise, the perception that performance exceeds expectations also rises. Both these findings will be discussed in detail in the next chapter. V-4. Results of the EOSM LISREL Analysis of Satisfied Clinton Voters and Dissatisfied Bush Voters In order to test the research hypothesis that satisfied and dissatisfied subjects process differently, the EOSM was reanalyzed using only satisfied Clinton voters (n=70) and dissatisfied Bush voters (n=88). Under ideal circumstances, Clinton voters would have been divided into satisfied versus dissatisfied groups, and Bush voters would have been divided into satisfied and dissatisfied groups, and two separate 2-group analysis would have been performed. However, small sample sizes of dissatisfied Clinton voters (n =6) and satisfied Bush voters (n = 8) precluded such analysis. Comparing satisfied Clinton and dissatisfied Bush voter results is a relatively weak analysis because differences between the two groups may be due to factors relating to voting behavior rather than level of satisfaction. Differences between the entire Clinton voter sample and satisfied Clinton voter sample is of more interest as the effects of removing dissatisfied voters can be examined. Similarly, differences between the entire Bush voter sample and dissatisfied Bush voter sample is of interest as the effects of removing satisfied voters can be examined. Results of such an analysis may provide insight into the question of differential processing based on level of satisfaction by examining the 203 changes in structural paths which result when the respective samples are made more homogeneous. Therefore, results will be presented in a manner which will facilitate such comparisons. In order to eliminate the possibility that paths would "disappear" simply because of a reduction in sample size, the analysis was performed with the same sample sizes specified as were used in the original EOSM analysis reported in Section v.2. Results of the analyses are presented in three tables. In the first, Table 35, unstandardized path estimates and standard errors of the satisfied Clinton voters are presented next to the same information for all Clinton voters. In the next table (Table 36) similar information is provided for dissatisfied Bush voters and all Bush voters. Finally, in Table 37, summary information drawn from the previous two tables is presented. Results of this analysis which relate to research hypothesis #3 are presented in the next section. In addition, it is possible to reexamine research hypothesis #1 and research hypothesis #2 using results from these more homogeneous samples; results of these analyses appear in Sections V.4.2 and V.4.3, respectively. V—4.1. Analysis of EOSM with Satisfied and Dissatisfied Voters - Results Related to Research Hypothesis #3 If Research hypothesis #3 is true, that is, if satisfied people process less extensively than dissatisfied people, one would expect fewer significant paths from pre-election variables to post-election variables, hereafter referred to as "pre - post paths," for the satisfied Clinton group relative to the total Clinton Group. This is because the total Clinton group includes some dissatisfied Clinton voters. In fact, the reverse is true: three such paths are significant 204 Table 35 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Unstandardized Estimates and Standard Errors of Structural Paths Satisfied Clinton Voters Versus All Clinton Voters Satisfied Clinton Voters Clinton Voters Unstd. Std. Unstd. Std. Estimates Errors Estimates Errors Structural Path To Overall Satisfaction from: Clinton Satisfaction .21 9* * * .082 .269* * .1 1 6 Bush Satisfaction .109* * * .061 .141* .091 Clinton Disconfirmation —> Clinton Satisfaction .368* * * .086 .376* * * .095 Bush Satisfaction .368" * * .127 .297* * .132 Bush Disconfirmation —> Clinton Satisfaction -.074 .104 -.101 .112 Bush Satisfaction .044 .154 .054 .1 58 Clinton Desires —> Clinton Disconfirmation .007 .010 -.001 .009 Clinton Satisfaction -.011* .007 .008 .007 Clinton Expectations —> Clinton Disconfirmation .002 .025 -.005 .023 Clinton Satisfaction -.008 .017 .001 .018 Clinton Attitude —> Clinton Satisfaction .005* * .003 .003 .003 Bush Desires —> Bush Disconfirmation .01 1 .010 .016* .009 Bush Satisfaction -.022* .01 5 -.01 8 .007 Bush Expectations —> Bush Disconfirmation -.016 .022 -.040* .021 Bush Satisfaction .031 .029 .025 .028 Bush Attitude —’ Bush Satisfaction .003 .003 .003 .004 * Signifcant at .10, 1-tail test * * Significant at .05, 1-tail test * * * Significant at .01, 1-taii test 205 Table 36 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Unstandardized Estimates and Standard Errors of Structural Paths Dissatisfied Bush Voters Versus All Bush Voters Dissatisfied Bush Voters Bush Voters Unstd. Std. Unstd. Std. Estimates Errors Estimates Errors Structural Path To Overall Satisfaction from: Clinton Satisfaction .41S* * * .063 .554* * * .098 Bush Satisfaction 253* * * .075 .250* * * .090 Clinton Disconfirmation -> Clinton Satisfaction .043 .058 .009 .066 Bush Satisfaction .067 .068 .066 .070 Bush Disconfirmation —> Clinton Satisfaction .251 * * * .068 .288* * * .077 Bush Satisfaction .269* * * .083 .307* * * .085 Clinton Desires —> Clinton Disconfirmation .01 3 .010 .006 .010 Clinton Satisfaction .01 1* * .006 .017* * * .007 Clinton Expectations —> Clinton Disconfirmation -.032* * .019 -.028* .019 Clinton Satisfaction -.001 .010 -.007 .012 Clinton Attitude ——> Clinton Satisfaction .003* * .001 .003” .001 Bush Desires -> Bush Disconfirmation -.004 .006 -.004 .006 Bush Satisfaction -.021* * * .016 -.024* * * .006 Bush Expectations —> Bush Disconfirmation -.03 3* * * .013 -.031* * .014 Bush Satisfaction .012 .01 1 .014* .01 1 Bush Attitude —> Bush Satisfaction .001 .002 .001 .002 * Signifcant at .10, 1-tail test * * Significant at .05, 1-tail test * * * Significant at .01, 1—tail test 206 Table 37 Election Outcome Satisfaction Model Summary of Differences in Model Results Using Ali/Satisfied Clinton Voters and All/Dissatisfied Bush Voters Clinton Voters Bush Voters 5.11m 811W Total number of significant paths 6 7 10 9 Total number of paths significant at .01 1 3 6 6 Total number of significant paths from pre-election to post-election variables 2 3 6 5 Total number of significant path from pre-election to post-election variables significant at .01 0 0 2 2 207 for satisfied Clinton voters versus two significant paths for all Clinton voters. For satisfied Clinton voters, the following paths are significant: Clinton Desire to Clinton Satisfaction, Clinton Attitude to Clinton Satisfaction, and Bush Desire to Bush Satisfaction. For the total Clinton sample, two paths are significant: Bush Desire to Bush Disconfirmation and Bush Expectation to Bush Disconfirmation. Note that no pre-post path which is significant for the entire Clinton group is also significant for the satisfied Clinton group. Thus, removal of dissatisfied Clinton voters significantly altered all pre-post relationships. The implication is that the relationship among pre-post variables is significantly different for satisfied versus dissatisfied Clinton voters. Therefore, although the research hypothesis is not supported in terms of the number of significant paths in each group, the evidence supmrts the idea that satisfied people and dissatisfied people process differently. Using similar logic, if research hypothesis #3 is true one would expect to observe more significant paths from pre-election to post-election variables for dissatisfied Bush voters relative to all Bush voters. However, fewer were observed (five versus six). For dissatisfied Bush voters, the following paths are significant: Clinton Desire to Clinton Satisfaction, Clinton Expectation to Clinton Satisfaction, Clinton Attitude to Clinton Satisfaction, Bush Desire to Bush Satisfaction, and Bush Expectation to Bush Disconfirmation. For all Bush voters, these same five paths are significant as is one additional path from Bush Expectation to Bush Satisfaction. That is, all five of the paths significant for the dissatisfied voter group were also significant for the entire voter group. The implication is that satisfied Bush voters are not very different from dissatisfied Bush voters in terms of pre - post variable relationships. 208 To summarize, we see that the dissatisfied Bush voter group had more significant paths (nine versus seven) and more pre - post variable paths (five versus three) than the satisfied Clinton voter group. Of the three significant pre - post paths for the satisfied Clinton group, one was significant at the .05 level and two were significant at .10. Of the five significant pre - post paths for dissatisfied Bush voters, three were significant at the .05 level and two were significant at .01. Thus, research hypothesis #3 receives mixed supmrt from this analysis. Strong support is provided by the finding that dissatisfied Bush voters do process more than satisfied Clinton voters while the shifts occurring within the Clinton and Bush voter groups does not support the research hypothesis. V-4.2. Analysis of EOSM with Satisfied and Dissatisfied Voters - Results Related to Research Hypothesis #1 It is possible to once again to examine research hypothesis #1, that multiple targets are relevant in satisfaction formation, using these more homogeneous subsamples of Clinton and Bush voters. We saw in the previous section that the significant paths connecting pre - post variables differed for satisfied Clinton and all Clinton voters. If research hypothesis #1 is true, we would expect to see paths to overall satisfaction from satisfaction with each target in a_ll subgroups analyzed. Among satisfied Clinton voters (Table 35), the paths from both satisfaction with Clinton and satisfaction with Bush to Overall Satisfaction are significant (p < .01, l-tail test). The major differences between the satisfied Clinton voter and all Clinton voter groups with regard to these paths are 1) that the path estimates are lower for the satisfied Clinton voters, and 2) that 209 the standard errors of each path estimate are lower for the satisfied Clinton voters. The net result is that each path is significant at a lower alpha level in the satisfied voter group. These relatively minor differences do not detract from the overall support for research hypothesis #1 provided by these results. Among Bush voters (Table 36), the same pattern of relationships is evident between dissatisfied Bush and all Bush voters as was true among satisfied Clinton voter versus all Clinton voters. That is, the paths from both Clinton Satisfaction and Bush Satisfaction to Overall Satisfaction are significant for all Bush voters and dissatisfied Bush voters. Once again, the major differences between the two groups are 1) that the path estimates are lower for the dissatisfied Bush voters, and 2) that the standard errors of each path estimate are lower for the dissatisfied Bush voters. In conclusionI analysis of both pairs of subsamples provides additional evidence in support of research hypothesi_s #1. V-4.3. Analysis of EOSM with Satisfied and Dissatisfied Voters - Results Related to Research Hypothesis #2 It is possible to examine research hypothesis #2, that the processing paths related to the two targets are related via cross-over paths, using these relatively homogeneous subsamples of Clinton and Bush voters. As research hypothesis #2 does not specify differences based on level of satisfaction, we would expect to see all subgroups exhibit significant cross-over effects if research hypothesis #2 is true. For Clinton voters, the cross-over path from Clinton disconfirmation to satisfaction with Bush remains significant (p < .01, l-tail test) in the satisfied Clinton voter group, as it was among all Clinton voters. In addition, the cross- 210 over path from Bush disconfirmation to satisfaction with Clinton remains nonsignificant for the satisfied Clinton voters as it was with the all Clinton voter group. For Bush voters, too, the cross-over path from Bush disconfirmation to Clinton satisfaction remains significant (p < .01, l-tail test) while the cross-over path from Clinton disconfirmation to Bush satisfaction remains nonsignificant for dissatisfied Bush voters. In conclusion, analysis of both pairs of subsamples provides additional mixed evidence in support of research hymthesis #2. Parenthetically, these results also support the contention made by Droge and Halstead (1991) that, unlike satisfied consumers, dissatisfied consumers appear to be expectations-driven. In this analysis, expectations are not related to other variables for the satisfied Clinton group, while expectations are significantly related to consequent variables for both Clinton and Bush among dissatisfied Bush voters. V-S. Results of the CPSM Correlation Analysis of Satisfied versus Dissatisfied Voters To test research hypothesis #3, differential processing of satisfied versus dissatisfied respondents, additional analysis was performed using CPSM data. There was significant variance within each group of the CPSM analysis with regard to overall satisfaction (see Figure 23). Therefore, correlation analysis of satisfied versus dissatisfied respondents within each voter group was performed (small sample sizes precluded the use of structural path analysis, which would have been more appropriate for testing the research hypothesis). 211 30 ‘r 27 -- 24 -- Z'l -- 18 ‘- 151— 1 2 ‘r 9 -i— _ “9% . 1 extremely extremely dissatisfied satisfied Clinton Voters I Bush Voters Figure 23 Overall Satisfaction with the Process (CPSM) 212 Dissatisfied voters were defined as those responding with a "1", "2" or "3" to the overall process satisfaction question. Satisfied voters were defined as those responding with a "S", "6" or "7" to the question. Voters who responded with a "4", the midpoint of the scale, were omitted from further analysis. Thus, four groups were created: Clinton voters satisfied with the process (n=40), Clinton voters dissatisfied with the process (n=27), Bush voters satisfied with the process (n=29) and Bush voters dissatisfied with the process (n=51). Separate correlation analyses were performed on each of the four groups. Results appear in Table 38. To test the research hypothesis that dissatisfied people process more extensively than do satisfied people, several simple counts of significant correlations (within each of the four groups) were made: 1) Total number of correlations significant at the .10 level; 2) Total number of correlations between any variable and overall satisfaction; and 3) Number of significant correlations between pre-election and post- election variables. Since simple correlations indicate two variables are linearly related, they are interpreted here as evidence of systematic processing by the relevant homogeneous subsample. A summary of the counts of significant correlations and some proportions based on the counts is presented in Table 39. Several observations from the table address research hypothesis #3. First, given the hypothesis, we would anticipate that there would be more significant correlations among dissatisfied voters than among satisfied voters. While there are slightly more significant correlations for dissatisfied versus satisfied Bush voters (23 versus 17), the reverse is true among Clinton voters 213 Table 38 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Subgroup Correlation Matrices Satisfied Clinton Voters 1 1.000 2 0.112 1.000 (.490) 3 -0.171 0.396 1.000 (0.306) (0.014) 4 0.292 0.219 0.426 1.000 (0.071) (0.180) (0.008) 5 0.331 -0.089 -0.393 -0.152 1.000 (0.037) 0.585 (0.015) (0.354) 6 0.327 0.005 -0.266 -0.045 0.614 1.000 (0.039) (0.974) (0.106) (0.768) (0.000) 7 0.175 0.128 -0.017 0.262 0.389 0.157 (0.285) (0.437) (0.921) (0.112) (0.014) (0.339) 6 0.616 -0.044 -0.180 0.364 0.084 0.114 (0.000) (0.789) (0.260) (0.023) (0.607) (0.486) 9 —0.187 0.269 0.021 -0.217 0.082 -0.240 (0.255) (0.098) (0.903) (0.191) (0.709) (0.141) 10 -0.236 0.321 0.160 -0.095 -0.308 -0.253 (0.143) (0.043) (0.338) (0.567) (0.053) (0.115) 11 0.057 0.142 0.453 0.210 -0.054 -0.167 (0.730) (0.388) (0.005) (0.207) (0.744) (0.310) 12 -0.340 0.063 0.531 0.052 -0.261 -0.194 (0.034) (0.615) (0.001) (0.754) (0.109) (0.236) 13 0.412 -0.023 -0.020 0.066 0.110 0.051 (0.009) (0.890) (0.905) (0.609) (0.504) (0.757) 14 -0.042 0.115 0.496 0.661 -0.327 -0.215 (0.601) (0.485) (0.002) (0.000) (0.043) (0.188) 1 2 3 4 5 6 W 1 Disconfhmtion re: Chton Advertishg Effectiveness 2 Disconfirmtion re: Chton Unfa's Campsignhg 3 Disconfimation re: Bush Advertbhg Effectiveness 4 Disconfimation re: Bah Unfai Carrpaignhg S Overal Disconfimation 6 Overal SatisfactionwithCarrpaign Process 1.000 0.165 1.000 (0.315) 0.400 -0.050 1.000 (0.012) (0.762) '0.105 -0.0i O 0.290 1.000 (0.524) (0.953) (0.073) 0.274 -0.111 0.212 -0.181 1.000 (0.092) (0.501) (0.196) (0.271) 0.176 -0.500 0.069 -0.018 0.567 1.000 (0.290) (0.001) (0.681) (0.913) (0.000) 0.087 0.243 -0.318 -0.179 0.418 0.112 1.000 (0.598) (0.138) (0.048) (0.275) (0.008) (0.501) 0.089 0.137 '0.362 0.049 0.323 0.294 0.259 1.000 (0.595) (0.406) (0.023) (0.769) (0.047) (0.069) (0.116) 7 8 9 1 0 1 1 1 2 1 3 1 4 W 7 Expectation re: Chton Ad. Effectiveness 8 Performance re: Chton Ad. Effectiveness Expectation re: Ciiton Unfa's Carrpsignhg Performance re: Chton Unfak Cannabnhg Expectation re: Bush Ad. Effectivenes Performance re: Bush Ad. Effectiveness Expectation rs: Bah Unfai Carmabnhg Perforrrnnce rs: Bah Unfak Carmabnhg 214 Table 38, continued Dissatisfied Clinton Voters 1 1.000 2 0.096 1.000 (0.633) 3 -0.039 0.175 1.000 (0.846) (0.382) 4 0.110 -0.206 -0.423 1.000 (0.591) (0.313) (0.031) 5 0.372 0.303 -0.019 0.015 1.000 (0.056) (0.125) (0.923) (0.941) 6 -0.220 0.141 0.246 -0.457 0.078 1.000 (0.270) (0.484) (0.215) (0.019) (0.698) 7 0.032 0.101 0.361 0.026 0.059 -0.120 (0.874) (0.616) (0.064) (0.899) (0.769) (0.550) 8 0.512 0.224 0.058 -0.309 0.013 0.089 (0.006) (0.261) (0.773) (0.125) (0.949) (0.658) 9 -0.336 0.309 -0.060 0.094 0.156 -0.205 (0.067) (0.117) (0.693) (0.683) (0.432) (0.305) 10 0.154 0.833 0.270 -0.353 0.371 -0.002 (0.442) (0.000) (0.173) (0.077) (0.056) (0.993) 1 1 -0.040 -0.117 0.307 -0.005 0.134 -0.392 (0.844) (0.562) (0.120) (0.981) (0.505) (0.043) 12 0.132 0.063 0.531 0.052 -0.261 -0.l94 (0.519) (0.572) (0.000) (0.172) (0.409) (0.180) 13 0.014 -0.064 0.180 0.149 0.077 ~0.194 (0.946) (0.752) (0.369) (0.469) (0.702) (0.332) 14 0.020 0.218 -0.041 0.602 -0.055 -0.266 (0.922) (0.274) (0.640) (0.001) (0.787) (0.147) 1 2 3 4 5 6 W l Disconfhnation re: Chton Advertishg Effectiveness 2 Disconfimation re: Cl'mton Unfa's Carrpaignhg 3 Disconfimation re: Bush Adverthhg Effectiveness 4 Disconfirmation re: Bah Unfair Carrpsigning 5 Overal Dbconfi'mation 6 Overal Satisfaction with Canpaign Process 1.000 0.224 1.000 (0.262) 0.407 -0.235 1.000 (0.035) (0.239) 0.207 0.323 0.290 1.000 (0.993) (0.100) (0.143) 0.475 -0.061 0.141 0.100 1.000 (0.012) (0.666) (0.482) (0.621) 0.203 -0.007 -0.162 0.051 0.226 1.000 (0.321) (0.974) (0.375) (0.603) (0.266) 0.562 -0.005 0.202 0.066 0.735 0.195 1.000 (0.002) (0.960) (0.312) (0.745) (0.000) (0.340) 0.260 -0.143 0.366 0.073 0.042 -0.079 0.433 1.000 (0.190) (0.476) (0.06) (0.716) (0.636) (0.701) (0.024) 7 6 9 10 11 12 13 14 William 7 Expectation re: Chton Ad. Effectiveness 8 Perforrmnce re; Chton Ad. Effectiveness 9 Expectation re: Chton Unfa's Carnpsignhg 10 Performance re: Chton Unfair Carmaignhg 1 1 Expectation re: Bush Ad. Effectivenes 12 Performance re: Bush Ad. Effectiveness 13 Expectation re: Bush Unfal' Carmebnhg 14 Performance re: Bah Unfai Carmabnhg 215 Table 38, continued Satisfied Bush Voters 1 1.000 2 -0.022 1.000 (0.909) 3 -0.052 -0.029 1.000 (0.789) (0.883) 4 0.311 0.316 0.295 1.000 (0.101) (0.095) (0.120) 5 -0.039 0.006 -0.023 -0.044 1.000 (0.642) (0.978) (0.904) (0.621) 6 0.030 -0.229 0.080 -0.181 0.350 1.000 (0.676) (0.231) (0.660) (0.349) (0.063) 7 0.443 -0.401 -0.050 -0.008 -0.002 0.157 (0.016) (0.031) (0.798) (0.968) (0.992) (0.366) 6 0.526 —0.150 0.191 -o.023 0.143 0.229 (0.003) (0.438) (0.320) (0.907) (0.460) (0.233) 9 -0.012 -0.025 0.092 -0.148 -0.116 -0.013 (0.951) (0.896) (0.635) (0.445) (0.551) (0.945) 10 0.096 0.675 0.145 0.156 0.015 -0.117 (0.62) (0.000) (0.453) (0.415) (0.938) (0.547) 11 -0.195 0.113 0.469 0.204 0.305 0.181 (0.312) (0.561) (0.007) (0.286) (0.108) (0.347) 12 -0.143 -0.152 0.362 0.132 0.064 -0.041 (0.458) (0.431) (0.041) (0.496) (0.664) (0.831) 13 0.289 -0.291 -0.072 0.200 0.169 0.228 (0.128) (0.125) (0.712) (0.297) (0.361) (0.234) 14 0.130 -0.066 0.086 0.335 0.276 0.067 (0.501) (0.733) (0.656) (0.076) (0.147) (0.728) 1 2 3 4 5 6 W l Disconfimation re: Chton Advertishg Effectiveness 2 Disconfirmation re: Cinton Unfai' Carnpaignhg 3 Disconfirmation re: Bush Advertisiig Effectiveness 4 Disconfimation re: Bush Unfai Carnpaignhg 5 Overal Disconfimation 6 Overal Satisfaction with Canpaim Process 1.000 0.617 1.000 (0.000) 0.300 0.256 1.000 (0.114) (0.180) -0.127 0.286 0.066 1.000 (0.513) (0.133) (0.732) -0.131 0.078 0.119 0.107 1.000 (0.497) (0.689) (0.537) (0.582) -0.021 0.053 0.283 -0.109 0.425 1.000 (0.915) (0.786) (0.137) (0.572) (0.021) -0.077 ~0.024 -0.324 ~0.378 0.315 0.178 1.000 (0.691) (0.902) (0.086) (0.043) (0.010) (0.355) -0.089 0.182 -0.123 -0.019 0.320 0.638 0.563 1.000 (0.648) (0.345) (0.526) (0.331) (0.090) (0.000) (0.002) 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 W 7 Expectation re: Chton Ad. Effectiveness 8 Performance re: Clinton Ad. Effectiveness 9 Expectation re: Ci'nton Unfair Carrpaignirg 10 Performance re: Chton Unfair Carmabnhg 1 1 Expectation re: Bush Ad. Effectivenee 12 Performance re: Bush Ad. Effectiveness 13 Expectation re: Bush Unfa's Carrpsignhg 14 Perforrrlnce re: Bah Unfai Canpsbnhg 216 Table 38, continued Dissatisfied Bush Voters 1 1.000 2 -0.069 1.000 (0.627) 3 -0.080 0.211 1.000 (0.579) (0.137) 4 -0.282 -0.125 0.271 1.000 (0.045) (0.382) (0.052) 5 -0.229 0.155 -0.066 0.029 1.000 (0.103) (0.273) (0.546) (0.837) 6 —0.180 0.172 0.004 0.265 0.542 1.000 (0.202) (0.222) (0.975) (0.056) (0.000) 7 -0.112 —0.044 0.116 0.168 0.213 0.152 (0.430) (0.759) (0.413) (0.182) (0.126) (0.277) 8 0.505 -0.050 -0.011 0.079 -0.121 -0.108 (0.000) (0.725) (0.937) (0.560) (0.391) (0.447) 9 0.317 0.007 0.131 0.094 -0.217 -0.080 (0.022) (0.923) (0.354) (0.509) (0.119) (0.568) 10 0.303 0.203 0.175 0.194 -0.135 0.009 (0.029) (0.149) (0.219) (0.173) (0.341) (0.946) 11 0.062 -0.186 0.165 0.101 -o.106 -0.361 (0.667) (0.196) (0.251) (0.464) (0.461) (0.009) 12 0.226 -0.137 0.352 0.271 -0.225 -0.245 (0.106) (0.334) (0.010) (0.052) (0.106) (0.077) 13 -0.255 -0.004 0.072 0.446 0.237 0.164 (0.074) (0.977) (0.620) (0.001) (0.095) (0.197) 14 -0.221 0.027 0.227 0.571 0.004 0.219 (0.116) (0.648) (0.106) (0.000) (0.979) (0.115) 1 2 3 4 5 6 W 1 Disconfimation re: Chton Advertis'ng Effectiveness 2 Disconfirmation re: Chton Unfai Carmaignhg 3 Disconfirmation re: BushAdvertislng Effectiveness 4 Disconfirmation re: Bah Unfa's Carrpaign'ng 5 Overal Disconfirnation 6 Overal SatisfactionwithCanpaign Process 1.000 0.043 1.000 (0.761) 0.366 0.382 1.000 (0.007) (0.005) 0.210 0.078 0.385 1.000 (0.136) (0.581) (0.005) -0.089 0.306 0.162 -0.130 1.000 (0.533) (0.031) (0.258) (0.367) -0.052 0.396 0.176 0.121 0.558 1.000 (0.711) (0.004) (0.206) (0.395) (0.000) 0.073 0.144 -0.019 -0.179 0.294 0.113 1.000 (0.612) (0.308) (0.896) (0.213) (0.036) (0.430) 0.031 -0.078 0.082 0.072 -0.060 0.199 0.339 1.000 (0.828) (0.584) (0.557) (0.612) (0.675) (0.153) (0.015) 7 8 9 1O 1 1 12 13 14 W 7 Expectation re: Chton Ad. Effectiveness 6 Performance re: Chton Ad. Effectiveness 9 Expectation re: Chton Unfa's Carmaignhg 10 Performance re: Chton Unfair Carmaignhg 1 1 Expectation re: Bush Ad. Effectivenes 12 Performance re: Bush Ad. Effectivenea 13 Exactation re: Bah Unfai Carnpabnhg 14 Performsnce re: Bah Unfai Canpaignhg 217 Table 39 Campaign Process Satisfaction Model Summary of Correlation Analysis Clinton Voters Bush Voters Satisfieg Dissatigfied Satisfied Dissatisfied Total number of significant correlations 30 19 17 23 Total number of significant correlations between any variable and overall satisfaction 2 2 1 4 Total number of significant correlations between pre-election and post-election variables 8 4 7 10 Proportion of significant correlations accounted for by pre-election and post-electionvariables .27 .21 .41 .43 218 (19 for dissatisfied versus 30 for satisfied voters). Second, if research hypothesis #3 is true, we would expect to see more significant correlations of any variable and overall satisfaction for dissatisfied versus satisfied voters. Again, for Bush voters, this is observed (four significant correlations for dissatisfied voters versus one for satisfied voters); also again, Clinton voters did not exhibit the hypothesized pattern (two significant correlations for each voter group). Third, one would expect to see more significant correlations between variables measured pre-election and variables measured post-election ("pre-post" correlations) for dissatisfied voters. This would provide the best indication of additional processing because the time difference between measurements of pre-election and post-election variables reduces the likelihood that factors other than processing are responsible for the correlations. Once again, dissatisfied Bush voters have more significant correlations than do satisfied Bush voters (10 versus 7), while satisfied Clinton voters have more significant correlations than do dissatisfied Clinton voters (8 versus 4). Finally, one might expect that the proportion of significant correlations accounted for by pre-post correlations would be higher for dissatisfied voters. The difference in these proportions between dissatisfied and satisfied Bush voters is very slight (.43 versus .41), while the difference in proportions for satisfied versus dissatisfied Clinton voters is slightly greater but in the opposite direction (.27 versus .21). Thus, these results provide, at best, weak support for research hypothesis #3. To determine whether the counts observed in Table 39 were due to the differences in sample sizes among the four groups, the smallest significant correlation (r = .24) which was significant in the dissatisfied Bush voter group (the largest group) was used as a threshold on all four groups, and the analysis 219 was repeated. No differences in the pattern of counts or in the general conclusions resulted. One possible explanation of these results, other than that satisfied and dissatisfied people do not process differently, is that overall campaign process satisfaction is less influential on processing than is the election outcome. Bush voters may be dissatisfied with the outcome of the election and this dissatisfaction, rather than satisfaction or dissatisfaction with the campaign process, may have dominated the determination of processing intensity. The difference between Bush voters and Clinton voters with respect to proportion of all correlations accounted for by pre-post correlations appears at first to support this explanation. If this explanas'on and research hypothesis #3 were both true, however, then Clinton voters satisfied with the process should have processed the least, which clearly did not occur. Further discussion of this issue, including another possible explanation for the pattern of findings, appears in the next chapter. 220 V-6. Summary of Results Relating to the Research Hypotheses In this section, selected results relating specifically to each research hypothesis are summarized and cross-referenced to other sections of the Results chapter. Note that a complete discussion of the results and their implications appear in the next chapter. 0 Research hypothesis 1: Multiple targets of satisfaction may remain salient post choice during satisfaction formation. Support for this hypothesis is found in 1) the EOSM using data from all Clinton and Bush voters (Section V-2.3), 2) the EOSM using data from satisfied Clinton voters and dissatisfied Bush voters (Section V-4.2), and 3) the CPSM using data from all Clinton and Bush voters (Section V-3.3). In both EOSM analyses, paths from both satisfaction with Clinton and satisfaction with Bush to Overall Satisfaction were significant for every group analyzed. Further, antecedent variables significantly impact consequent variables within the paths associated with each target, choice and non-choice in the EOSM and CPSM analyses. When one considers that the EOSM and CPSM use different variables and different structural forms, yet yield similar results with regard to this hypothesis, we can conclude thgt research hymthesis #1 is strongly supported. This finding is probably the most important contribution of this dissertation research as it clearly demonstrates that the traditional CS/ D model with its focus on a single target is overly simplistic. 221 0 Research hypothesis 2: The processing paths associated with each of the multiple targets of satisfaction are interrelated, i. e. there are cross-over effects. Support for this hypothesis is found in the EOSM using data for all voters (Section V—2.4) and also using data from satisfied Clinton and dissatisfied Bush voters (Section V-4.3). In all four groups analyzed (Clinton voters, satisfied Clinton voters, Bush voters, dissatisfied Bush voters), the cross-over path from disconfirmation with the choice to satisfaction with the non-choice is significant while the cross-over path from disconfirmation with the non- choice to satisfaction with the choice is not significant. Thus, there is strong support for the existence of a cross-over effect but the effect is not as extensive as hyppthesized (i.e., there is no support for the disconfirmation with non-choice - satisfaction with the choice path). In addition, there is evidence that cross-over effects not hypothesized specifically may occur elsewhere along the satisfaction formation paths. For example, in the EOSM, the single largest modification index (12.049) is for the non-modeled path Bush Expectation to Clinton Satisfaction among Bush voters (Table 24). In addition, several of the large standardized residuals are for cross-over relationships such as Bush Desire - Clinton Satisfaction (-3.225) and Clinton Desire - Bush Disconfirmation (2.489) among Bush voters, and Bush Attitude - Clinton Satisfaction (2.431) and Clinton Attitude - Bush Satisfaction (2.452) among Clinton voters. Thus, while there is strong support for a cross-over effect, the exact nature and extent of such an effect cannot be resolved from these results alone. 222 0 Research hypothesis 3: Dissatisfied subjects process more extensively or completely than do satisfied subjects. Support for this hypothesis is found in the EOSM analysis of satisfied Clinton and dissatisfied Bush voters (Section V-4.1) and the EOSM analysis of all Clinton and all Bush voters (Section V-2.4). In both analyses, there are more significant paths associated with Bush voters and dissatisfied Bush voters than with Clinton voters and satisfied Clinton voters. In addition, in both analyses, there are more significant paths connecting variables measured pre-election and variables measured post-election for the dissatisfied groups. However, contrary to what one would expect given research hypothesis #3, the number of significant pre - post paths 1) increased when dissatisfied Clinton voters were removed from all Clinton voters, and 2) decreased when satisfied Bush voters were removed from all Bush voters. In short, the hymthesis is supported in thgt dissatisfied voters do process more than do satisfied voters, but it is not supmrted in that the minor changes which occur within each voter group as that group becomes more homogeneous are oppogte to th_at hypothesized. The CPSM correlation analysis (Section v.5) does not support the hypothesis in its current form, though it does support the idea that satisfied and dissatisfied voters process differently. 0 Research hypothesis 4: Desires have a greater impact on satisfaction formation than do expectations. Support was found for research hypothesis #4. Results of the total (direct and indirect) effects of both desires and expectations on the various satisfaction measures of the EOSM were directly compared in Section V-2.6. 223 Where differences between the two exist, desires appear to have greater effects than expectations on all three satisfaction measures. Further, we saw that a total of three high modification indices indicated relationships between desires and overall satisfaction while only one high modification index indicated a similar expectations - overall satisfaction link (Table 24). Thus, the hypothesis is supported. Chapter VI Discussion and Implications The purpose of this research was to develop and test a model of satisfaction formation which explicitly accounted for the effects of both choice and nonchoice targets. Two models were specified and tested using data from the 1992 U.S. presidential election. Though not all hypothesized path relationships in each model are supported by the data, as a whole, the results provide moderate-to—strong support for each of the four research hypotheses. Detailed results, and brief interpretations, are presented in the previous chapter. In this chapter, the theoretical and practical implications of the findings are discussed, directions for future research are highlighted, and the research limitations are presented. This chapter is organized as follows. In the next section, VI—l, the results and implications related to the first two research hypotheses are discussed. Together, these two hypotheses provide the framework for the competitive model of satisfaction formation. In Section VI-2, results and implications related to research hypothesis #3, differential processing associated with level of satisfaction, are discussed. In Section VI—3, results and implications related to research hypothesis #4, the relative importance of desires versus expectations, are discussed. In Section VI-4, other findings are discussed in relation to past research including: the relationship of expectations to disconfirmation and to satisfaction (VI-4.1), disconfirmation (VI—4.2), attitudes (VI-4.3), and the context of this research (VI-4.5). limitations of the research are presented in VI-S. Finally, in VI-6, brief concluding remarks are presented. 224 225 VI-l. The Competitive Model of Satisfaction Formation Because it is impossible to discuss separately the implications of multiple targets (research hypothesis #1) and the nature of their effects (research hypothesis #2), and because these two research hypotheses together provide the competitive model's structure, the discussion in this section addresses both hypotheses. The finding that multiple targets may be relevant to satisfaction formation is probably the most significant result of this dissertation. It implies that satisfaction formation is subject to competitive forces, at least in an election context. Further, it implies that the traditional model of satisfaction formation may be fundamentally flawed in the context of an election and perhaps in other situations. First, it should be noted that the satisfaction formation model developed here does not reg uire that competitive forces be included. For situations in which competition is not relevant, path values for all but the choice target may be specified as zero. For many applications, therefore, the currently accepted single target model may be utilized. However, for situations in which nonchoices remain salient post-purchase, the proposed model should be used with nonchoice paths estimated. The multiple targets are relevant to the extent they affect the concept of "overall satisfaction." Consumers are ultimately attempting to satisfy some need or want, i.e., they are attempting to have a satisfying consumption experience. This dissertation has demonstrated that the concept of overall satisfaction is relevant and is the result of satisfaction with multiple competitive targets, at least in the context of head-to-head, zero-sum competition. 226 One powerful implication of an overall satisfaction construct is that it can account for competition even among competitive choices which are difficult to compare directly, such as "sequenced" choices. For example, assume someone wants to have a nice-looking lawn. He recognizes that he can cut his lawn himself or hire a lawn service to do so. He decides to cut the lawn himself and considers buying one of two lawn mowers, Brand A or Brand B. He selects Brand A. He is satisfied with the performance of his choice mower, especially given that a neighbor bought a Brand B mower and has had several problems with it. But, he is dissatisfied with his choice to select a mower at all, especially given that his other neighbor has hired a lawn service and thus has a better-looking lawn and more leisure time than does our subject. The traditional satisfaction model would specify that satisfaction is the result of antecedents related only to the Brand A mower. The competitive satisfaction model as discussed thus far would add the antecedents of and "satisfaction" with the Brand B mower as well. However, this same model could be expanded further to include the antecedents of and "satisfaction" with the lawn service, too. Although the subject may be perfectly satisfied with the mower per se, overall he is less satisfied because the lawn service was not chosen. We see that the model can be specified in a manner which mirrors the competitive reality in which the total consumption experience is occurring. From a managerial perspective, this enhances the usefulness of the model. As discussed earlier, traditional models attempt to incorporate competitive factors through the disconfirmation standard. However, even the most realistic of these, best brand norms and ideal brand norms, are product-related rather than consumption experience related. The Brand A mower manufacturer 227 using the traditional model would have no way of examining postconsumption processes in a meaningful way. The concept of overall satisfaction, coupled with the recognition that multiple targets can remain salient postchoice, provides a potentially powerful tool both theoretically and managerially. To take full advantage of this potential, future research needs to examine the degree to which non-comparable nonchoices can be included via the concept of overall satisfaction. Finding support for the hypothesized cross-over effect in the EOSM is also extremely significant. Evidence of this effect suggests that the processes associated with each of the relevant targets are themselves interrelated. The traditional satisfaction literature treats competing products as being irrelevant or as being relevant as a comparison standard at a single point only (see Section II-3.5). For those models in which competing products are used as a comparison standard, the comparison is operationalized in the disconfirmation construct. The evidence here suggests that utilizing competing products in only this manner is overly simplistic. A person's perceived disconfirmation of a choice product may affect satisfaction with the choice and also with the nonchoice. That this is true in a head-to-head competitive situation is relatively easy to accept. For a Bush voter, whether Bush did better or worse than expected is directly tied to whether Clinton did better or worse than expected, so it is not surprising that disconfirmation of Bush's performance affects satisfaction with each candidate. Awaiting further study is the issue of whether similar cross-over effects may also exist elsewhere along the processing path. For example, an examination of the EOSM modification indices reveals that freeing the path from Bush Expectation to Clinton Satisfaction would greatly improve model fit. 228 Also, it is likely that if perceived performance were included in a similar model (i.e., one without clear, objective and widely understood performance measures), there may be cross-over paths to or from it. For example, what one expects or desires to occur relative to one's choice may reasonably influence perceived performance of one's nonchoice. Likewise, perceived performance of one's nonchoice may affect satisfaction with one's choice, both indirectly through disconfirmation as well as directly. Obviously, both theoretical and empirical attention is necessary with regard to this issue. What is the practical meaning of such a cross-over effect in a non-zero- sum competitive context? In Section [-3, an example was used to illustrate the effect. A husband and wife each purchased a car at approximately the same time. They discussed their selection process and each formed expectations and desires regarding their own choice and the choice of the spouse (their "nonchoice"). They each usually drive their own car but occasionally drive (and often ride in) their spouse's car. If the husband is asked his level of satisfaction with his car, it seems reasonable that, in addition to his perceived performance and disconfirmation related to his own car, his disconfirmed expectations of his wife's car would affect his satisfaction with his car. One might argue that the husband has had extensive direct experience with his wife's car and therefore the situation is not typical of consumer products in general. Other forms of "experience" may provide enough information for a similar process to occur in other situations. Two categories of such experiences may be actual past experience or vicarious experience (Houston, Sherman, and Baker 1991). Fi_rs_t_, actual past experience with a competing brand may provide a salient nonchoice during satisfaction formation, especially if the current choice is a trial purchase. Second, 229 vicarious experience may also support powerful nonchoice processing. Seeing others drive a car you almost purchased, reading performance data about the car in Consumer Reports. seeing advertisements about the car, etc., all can reasonably support parallel nonchoice, postpurchase satisfaction processing. Of course, the situations under which interrelated processing occurs can be identified and delineated through empirical testing; however, it seems likely that such processes occur even when direct experience is absent. Evidence of cross-over effects also has important managerial implications. For firms associated with the customer's choice (choice firms), opportunities for pre-emptive defensive marketing exist. Choice firms can manage customer satisfaction with the choice through customer service and quality control programs. They can also affect their customer's satisfaction with nonchoices. Immediately after making a choice, customers begin attempting to reduce dissonance caused by the act of choosing. Such dissonance occurs because of 1) positive aspects of the nonchoices, and 2) negative aspects of the choice (Festinger 1957). Some firms attempt to capitalize on this consumer tendency, reinforcing the customer's decision by highlighting positive aspects of the choice postpurchase. The opportunity also exists for choice firms to take actions which reduce satisfaction with nonchoices, i.e., a form of "blocking." This topic has not been addressed and is in need of exploration. For example, for some products, providing customers (or specific segments of customers) with comparative information postpurchase may be more effective than simply saying "congratulations with your new purchase" in 1) increasing satisfaction with the choice, and 2) decreasing satisfaction with the nonchoice. Of course, such tactics have significant inherent risks similar to those associated with comparative 230 advertising; however, the potential payoff as a defensive tactic is significant enough to warrant further investigation. Similarly, for firms associated with the customer's nonchoices (nonchoice firms) opportunities for offensive marketing may exist. The existence of cross-over paths imply that nonchoice firms should not focus only on competition during the consumer's decision-making period. Instead, competitive actions immediately following purchase of the choice should be considered. The message from this research is "don't wait until the customer is ready to purchase again." Nonchoice firms should attempt to counteract the tendency of consumers to reduce postpurchase dissonance. Specifically, they can try to increase the customer's attention towards negative aspects of the choice and towards positive aspects of the nonchoice. There is evidence that some firms have begun to do this. For example, food retailers have recently begun to offer a service to nonchoice firms at the checkout stand. If a consumer purchases brand A tomato soup, the consumer receives a cents-off coupon for purchasing brand B tomato soup within the next month. Such a strategy may be extended to nonprice elements of the marketing mix. Similarly, activities directed towards reducing satisfaction with the choice are beginning to appear. For example, an American automobile dealership near Flint, Michigan, has begun to market auto maintenance services via direct mail to purchasers of foreign-made automobiles. The featured message is: "foreign car dealers often overcharge for parts and service. Though you recently purchased a foreign car, consider having it serviced at an American car dealership." As relationship marketing arenas become more widespread, competition during postpurchase processes will be likely to increase; the 231 model presented here provides a framework for analyzing competitive forces during these processes. Another area for future research is the examination of which nonchoices remain salient post-purchase. It may be possible to investigate empirically the contents of consumer choice sets, or at least those elements of the choice set which were most seriously considered, by identifying those nonchoices which remain salient in post-purchase processes. Knowledge of which nonchoices remain salient post-purchase would lead to questions of why some nonchoices remain important while others do not. Answers to these questions would be of critical interest to managers seeking to devise specific strategies for gaining competitive advantages in this important but under- researched competitive arena. The extension of the model presented here to multiple nonchoices is theoretically straightforward but raises significant measurement problems. One potential problem with using this type of model is that data collection and analysis may be cumbersome if large numbers of nonchoices remain salient. To add one additional nonchoice increases the volume of basic data required by 50%. Adding two additional nonchoices would double the amount of data required. If multiple measures and/ or multiple attributes are included, questionnaire length quickly becomes excessive. Also, as the number of salient nonchoices increases, the sample size required to estimate the model also increases quickly because the number of paths to be estimated increases more than arithmetically (if all theoretically relevant paths are included). For example, adding candidate Perot to the model in this dissertation would have resulted in the estimation of 27 paths for the EOSM (versus the 16 paths 232 currently estimated). Using the rule of thumb that a minimum sample size should be five times the number of paths to be estimated, the minimum 11 required for each group would increase from about 80 to about 135. So adding one candidate would have required an additional 1 10 subjects (assuming we were not also interested in Perot voters) and a questionnaire about 50% longer. Still, collecting sufficient data on one or two nonchoices is feasible and productive, and may be all that is required to address the majority of situations in which the traditional CS/ D model is inadequate. VI-2. Differential Processing The results presented in Chapter 5 provide support for the research hypothesis that dissatisfied voters process more extensively than do satisfied voters. Strongest support comes from results associated with the EOSM; these results will be reviewed briefly here to introduce the subsequent discussion. Arguably, the number of paths linking pre-election and post-election variables is indicative of amount of processing (see Section III-2.3). Six of ten such paths are significant for Bush voters while two of ten are significant for Clinton voters (Table V-6). Somewhat surprising is the decrease in number of significant paths for Bush voters and the increase in number of significant paths for Clinton voters when each sample is made more homogeneous with regard to overall satisfaction. Looking first at the Clinton voters, the fact that the Bush desires - disconfirmation and Bush expectation - disconfirmation paths both become nonsignificant when neutral and dissatisfied Clinton voters are removed indicates that these voters were disproportionately influenced by their focus on Bush, and especially by their expectations regarding Bush (note the 233 change in size of the parameter estimate from -.040 to -.016 in Table V-16). Note also that all pre-post paths shifted for the Clinton voter sample: neither path significant before removal of the neutral/ dissatisfied Clinton voters remained significant. All the paths added were related to desires and attitudes, not expectations. For Bush voters, the removal of satisfied and neutral voters had a different effect. Though one path went from being just significant to being just nonsignificant (the parameter estimate dropped from .014 to .012 while the standard error remained the same), the other two paths involving expectations experience slight increases in their unstandardized estimates and increases in level of significance. All significant paths following removal of satisfied/neutral Bush voters were also significant for the entire Bush sample. The implication is that, if anything, expectations were disproportionately more important to dissatisfied voters. Collectively, these findings from the EOSM are consistent with the Droge and Halstead (1991) contention that dissatisfied people are more expectations- driven than are satisfied people. It is also consistent with cognitive dissonance theory which would predict that dissatisfied voters probably experience dissonance and thus are motivated to attempt to reduce the dissonance by processing and reprocessing relevant cognitions. Satisfied voters do not experience dissonance among these cognitions and thus are not motivated to process. It is tempting to speculate that an elaboration likelihood model (ELM) explanation of this phenomenon is relevant (Petty and Cacioppo 1986). Petty and Cacioppo state that people tend to process peripherally unless they have the ability and motivation to process centrally. It is likely that in the context 234 of a presidential election and this particular study sample, most respondents possess the ability to process the EOSM variables, so what separates those who do and do not process centrally must be motivation. Thus, from the results presented here, it appears that satisfaction/ dissatisfaction may be a determinant of central versus peripheral processing. The problem with this statement, of course, is that Clinton and Bush voters differ in ways other than simply their level of satisfaction/ dissatisfaction, and it may be one or more of these other differences which account for the differences in processing route. One such interesting difference, the one with the greatest potential to provide a theoretical explanation of differential processing route, is magnitude of disconfirmation. With regard to both Bush's and Clinton's performance, Bush voters have a greater absolute level of disconfirmation than do Clinton voters (where "absolute level of disconfirmation" is defined as the absolute value of the difference between mean disconfirmation and "4," the midpoint of the disconfirmation scale). Results of the EOSM analysis are consistent with both the disconfirmation and satisfaction/dissatisfaction explanation of processing route. That is, Bush voters are more likely to process extensively ("centrally") and both 1) are more dissatisfied, and 2) have greater absolute disconfirmation than do Clinton voters. However, if absolute level of disconfirmation and n_ot satisfaction/ dissatisfaction per se determine amount of processing, then a group which is satisfied and has greater absolute disconfirmation will process more than a group which is dissatisfied and has lo_wpr_' absolute levels of disconfirmation. The CPSM data allows us to examine this situation. In the CPSM, Clinton voters have higher overall satisfaction and also slightly higher absolute value of disconfirmation. Thus, one might expect that 235 Clinton voters would exhibit greater processing than do Bush voters; in fact, such appears to be the case, as 15 paths are significant for Clinton voters, while 9 are significant for Bush voters (Table V-13). Also, there are more significant correlations among Clinton voters than among Bush voters (Tables V-19 and V-20). Of course, the CPSM does not provide an ideal set of variables for testing this idea: though "satisfaction with process" is the relevant satisfaction variable for the model, it is likely that peoples' overall satisfaction is dominated by the election outcome. Thus, even Clinton voters dissatisfied with the process are likely to be satisfied overall while Bush voters satisfied with the process are likely to be dissatisfied overall. (This factor may be driving the high proportion of significant correlations attributable to variables paired with "expectations," the one pre-election variable in this model). Investigating this issue further is beyond the scope of this dissertation. However, future research could address the issue by directly comparing high versus low absolute value disconfirmation treatments and high versus low satisfaction levels; such a comparison could best be accomplished using an experimental or quasi-experimental design. Disconfirmation possesses a few characteristics which make it theoretically preferable to satisfaction as a determinant of processing route. Because it occurs prior to satisfaction in any causal model, it is more likely to be able to explain why processing is central versus peripheral. For a pre-post relationship to be significant, only the "post" variable is subject to adjustment post-performance (assuming the "pre" variable is actually measured pre- performance). Disconfirmation, the judgment of the performance - expectation relationship, is the most likely place such an adjustment could 236 occur. By the time satisfaction/dissatisfaction is formed, presumably all pre- post relationships have been established, and thus satisfaction/dissatisfaction does not determine processing path but can only function as a classification variable after the fact; i.e., something else is responsible for the differential processing and disconfirmation seems the most reasonable construct for performing this function. It may be difficult to test this idea in a typical marketing context because of the difficulty of positively disconfirming expectations to the same extent they can be negatively disconfirmed. Expectations are generally high so there is a lot of "room" for performance to fall short of expectations, but little room to exceed expectations in most commercial settings. Because of this asymmetry, observations that dissatisfaction is associated with increased processing are indistinguishable from observations that high absolute value disconfirmation is associated with increased processing. To address this issue well, the larger issue of what exactly disconfirmation is must be resolved. The multiple serious problems with both the conceptualization and operationalization of disconfirmation are discussed in Section 11.3.5. There is strong evidence that disconfirmation of standards other than expectations (e.g., desires) is more appropriate theoretically and empirically (Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987; Spreng and Olshavsky 1993; Westbrook and Reilly 1983). The existence and maybe even the source of differential processing based on level of satisfaction/dissatisfaction can be addressed, but completely understanding the determinants of central versus peripheral processing route selection will probably have to wait until the questions surrounding disconfirmation are resolved. 237 The heightened relevance of expectations among dissatisfied Bush voters may also be due, in part, to an "inoculation" effect; that is, Bush voters may have artificially lowered their expectations of Bush in an attempt to moderate their ultimate level of dissatisfaction. Polls had consistently showed Bush to have less support than Clinton. Though data which would have shed light on this issue were not collected, such an effect would have been entirely consistent with regret theory. VI-3. Total Effects of Desires versus Expectations Expectations has long been a key antecedent variable in models of satisfaction formation (Czepiel and Rosenberg 1977; Miller 1977; Swan 1981). While desires is a relatively recent addition to the literature, it has strong theoretical and empirical support (see Section II-3.2). The purpose of research hypothesis #4 was to investigate the relative importance of these two variables on satisfaction formation. From Chapter V, we see that, for both Clinton and Bush voters, desires have greater direct and indirect effects on all three satisfaction measures than do expectations. In addition, desires appears to provide unique explanatory power. One might expect that, especially in a political context, desires and attitudes would be highly correlated, but such is not the case in this research (desires - attitude correlations range from -.09 to .52). Logically, this is not surprising. The use of expectations in satisfaction models, both independently and as a comparison standard for disconfirmation, has multiple conceptual problems (e.g., Cadotte, Woodruff, and Jenkins 1987; Spreng 1992; Tse and Wilton 1988). On the other hand, the case can be made that satisfaction is dependent, at least in part, on the extent to which 238 performance is consistent with desires (Spreng 1992; Boulding et a1 1993). In addition, the modification indices for the EOSM indicate that the addition of paths from desires to other consequent variables may significantly improve the fit of the model. Clearly, additional examination of desires as an antecedent variable in satisfaction formation is warranted. One important issue needing resolution is how desires differ from similar constructs, most notably, from ideals. Others have addressed the question (e.g., Spreng and Dixon 1992; Tse and Wilton 1988) but there has been no resolution which has been subjected to empirical verification. The distinction is complicated by the reality that people are usually faced with constrained choices. In this research, for example, gm that Bush was the Republican nominee, is there any difference between "desiring Bush to win the election" and "Bush is the ideal candidate on the ballot to win the election?" On the other hand, under no constraints, wouldn't one desire the ideal? Again, in this context, it seems that many Republicans would "desire" a Reagan clone because that is their "ideal," while many Democrats would desire a Kennedy clone. If, as some suggest, the difference is the reality constraint, there should be no confusion as long as the constraints (or lack of constraints) are clearly understood. The relatively low correlations between desires and attitudes is somewhat surprising. There are two possible explanations. First, attitude was measured as the summation of beliefs times importance for four attributes. Though there is strong support for selecting these four attributes, it is possible that other variables were salient to respondents. Desires, being operationalized generally, could be based on anything the respondents considered important. Second, the issue of reality constraints may be relevant. 239 The implicit standard for the belief component of attitude measurement is an ideal (i.e., the ideal candidate would receive a "10" on each belief measure). It is very likely that some voters rated a candidate low on a belief item, but still gave the candidate a high desires score because, given the limited choices, that candidate was the most desired. For example, Clinton voters may have rated Clinton low on a particular attribute (e.g., personal integrity) but still assigned him all 100 points in the desires question because they did not want Bush or Perot at all. Similarly, Bush voters could have rated Bush low on a particular attribute (e.g., domestic economy) but still assigned him all 100 points in the desires questions to indicate they did not want Clinton or Perot. Finally, the issue of how best to measure desires needs to be resolved. Desires may refer to a "more is better" versus an "ideal point" attribute, and measurement scales may have to differ accordingly. Also, researchers should address whether "desired outcome" or "strength of desires" is the most appropriate construct for a given situation. While the desires scale used in this research may have been flexible, interpretation of responses is difficult in this regard. If a voter responded in terms of "desired outcome," a rating of 100 points implies he or she wanted the other candidates to receive 0% of the vote. Is this really the outcome desired? On the other hand, a response of 100 points in a "strength of desires" context implies the respondent felt no ambivalence towards the candidate. Both interpretations of a desires question - desired outcome versus strength of desires -- are reasonable in different contexts, depending on the exact research question of interest. When "desired outcome" is the relevant construct and choice is binary, perhaps desires should be operationalized as a categorical choice. When "strength of desires" 240 is relevant (for example, if one is trying to assess how difficult it would be to change desires), a continuous scale seems to be the appropriate measurement tool. Desires may be more congruent with the affective nature of satisfaction than are expectations. Some early researchers conceptualized satisfaction as a "judgment" implying that cognitive factors alone could account for the satisfaction formation process. Recently, however, satisfaction researchers have been focusing more and more on the affective dimension of satisfaction (e.g., Oliver and Westbrook 1991; Oliver and Mano 1993; Oliver 1993). Affective elements of anticipation may be more accurately captured with a "desire" construct than with an "expectation" construct. The findings presented in this study are consistent with such an interpretation. To make the case that desires should be included as a "standard" antecedent variable in satisfaction formation models, the following should be demonstrated: 1) there are significant theoretical reasons for including desires as an antecedent variable, 2) "desires" are distinct from other antecedent constructs currently included in such models, and 3) there is empirical evidence that desires functions in this manner across multiple contexts. The first requirement was addressed in Chapter II. The second and third requirements are supported by the findings of this research. One important requirement for future research is to determine whether "desires" functions in its capacity as an important antecedent variable across a wide variety of contexts using multiple methods. One important implication of this finding is that managers should not be urged to manage satisfaction by manipulating only expectations and performance quality. In addition to the obvious risk of "under-selling" a 241 product's benefits in a competitive environment, the focus on expectations (which are relatively easy to manipulate) versus desires (which are difficult to manipulate) is on shaky theoretical and empirical ground. VI-4. Other Findings in Relation to Past Research This section contains a discussion of the results of the current research which do not neatly fit into one of the research hypotheses but which are interesting when considered in relation to previous research. VI-4.1. The Relationship of Expectations to Disconfirmation and to Satisfaction The relationship between expectations and satisfaction in the competitive satisfaction model presented here is similar to the relationship described in the satisfaction literature. However, the signs of these paths illustrates a point often omitted in discussions of this relationship: the path is positive when the expectations refer to a desired trait and negative when the expectations refer to an undesired trait. In most previous research, expectations are usually expectations with regard to a desired trait, and so the relationship is hypothesized to be positive. In cases of head-to-head competition a trait may be desirable for both alternatives, undesirable for both alternatives, desirable for one's choice and undesirable for one's nonchoice, or undesirable for one's choice and desirable for one's nonchoice. In the process model, for example, advertising effectiveness was an element which was desirable for one's own candidate and undesirable for the opposing candidate. Thus, for Clinton voters, the relationship was positive with respect to Clinton's advertising effectiveness and negative with respect to Bush's 242 advertising effectiveness. The opposite is true for Bush voters. However, no one wanted Clinton or Bush to run an unfair campaign. Thus, the relationship between expectations and satisfaction was negative for both Bush and Clinton voters. In other words, a competitive model of satisfaction introduces an additional element of complexity even to relationships about which consensus exists. Similarly, the relationship between expectations and disconfirmation appears to be more complex in this competitive model than in the traditional model. Expectations have been thought to affect satisfaction directly as well as indirectly through disconfirmation (Yi 1990) The expectations - disconfirmation relationship is generally thought to be negative, i.e., as expectations rise the judgment that performance meets or exceeds expectations decreases. Of the eight expectations - disconfirmation paths in the CPSM, five are significant; two of the five observed relationships are positive. The positive paths appear for campaign elements which logically are undesirable for a particular group. Specifically, Clinton voters probably would not want Clinton to run an unfair campaign, nor would they want Bush's advertising to be effective. In both cases, the positive expectations - disconfirmation path is paired with a negative expectations - satisfaction path, consistent with the current understanding of both direct and indirect effects of expectations on satisfaction (albeit with both signs opposite to those generally reported). For the two similar paths for Bush voters (expectation of Clinton's advertising effectiveness and its related disconfirmation, and expectation of Bush's unfair campaign and its disconfirmation), the signs are also positive, though the paths are not significant. 243 More puzzling, however, is the pattern of relationships of expectations - disconfirmation and performance - disconfirmation for these elements. In both cases, the performance - disconfirmation relationship is positive, too. These relationships seem to be illogical because they imply that people are more likely to judge that performance exceeds expectations the higher expectations are. One possible explanation of this phenomenon is that the relevant "expectation" used to make the disconfirmation judgment differs for desirable versus undesirable elements. It is possible that retrieved expectations form the basis for disconfirmation judgments when an element is undesirable while actual expectations form the basis for the comparison for desirable elements. Alternatively, it is possible that both comparisons rely on retrieved expectations, but that retrieved expectations for desirable elements remain similar to actual expectations while retrieved expectations for undesirable elements decrease relative to actual expectations. Finally, it is possible that expectations for undesirable elements have a greater impact on perceptions of performance than do expectations regarding desirable elements. That is, high expectations for an undesirable element bias individuals to perceive performance as being "worse" (more undesirable) whereas the same does not occur for desirable elements. It is well-accepted that consumers "over value" negative information in decision-making processes (e.g., Mizerski 1982; Richins 1983); perhaps different satisfaction formation processes operate when negative elements are explicitly considered. Given recent fruitful work on the distinction between retrieved versus prior expectations (Drtige and Halstead 1991; Halstead 1993), future research should start with that distinction as a possible explanation of the findings reported here. 244 VI-4.2. Disconfirmation Although not a focus of the dissertation, results do shed light on the utility of the disconfirmation model of satisfaction formation. Disconfirmation with each candidate's performance is a significant antecedent of satisfaction with the chosen candidate for both groups in the EOSM. Also, overall disconfirmation is the dominant predictor of overall process satisfaction in the CPSM. To this extent, the findings illustrate at least the predictive ability of disconfirmation. However, two caveats are necessary. First, because no subjective measures of performance are included, the strength of the disconfirmation - satisfaction relationship may be overstated in the EOSM. Second, while high in predictive ability, subjective disconfirmation lacks strong theoretical meaning. This problem is illustrated by the absence of links with variables which ought (theoretically) to be antecedent to disconfirmation in both the CPSM and EOSM. One problem with the traditional CS/ D conceptualization of disconfirmation is that the standard is £11 internal (e.g., expectations, desires) or pply external (e.g., best brand, experience based norms). In other words, something important is excluded though there is strong theoretical and empirical support that both internal and external standards are relevant. With the proposed model, both internal and external factors are included in the satisfaction formation process. Finally, after data were collected for this research, the concept of "desires congruency" was introduced to the literature (Spreng and Olshavsky 1993). This is basically a measure of the degree to which performance matches desires. In the present research, such a measure of congruency was not included, but a path from desires to disconfirmation of expectations was 245 estimated. This may have resulted in an inflation of the apparent effects of disconfirmation on satisfaction; in the future, the more theoretically- attractive construct of desires congruency should be included also, with it (and not disconfirmation) mediating the effects of desires. VI-4.3. Attitudes The significance of some attitude - satisfaction links in the EOSM has implications for the inclusion of attitude as an antecedent variable in future research. As discussed in Section II-3.3, despite the reasonable theoretical arguments for including attitude in satisfaction formation models, empirical support for including this construct has been weak or non-existent. In the EOSM, attitude towards Clinton was a significant predictor of satisfaction with Clinton among _Bpph voters (Table V-6). In fact, among Bush voters, attitude towards Clinton is a more important predictor of satisfaction with Clinton that is expectation or even disconfirmation. In previous satisfaction research, antecedents of satisfaction with nonchoices have not been included. Perhaps it is attitude towards nonchoices which is more relevant and that is why previous research has been unable to establish the relevance of attitude empirically. In addition, attitude towards Clinton was a significant antecedent of satisfaction with Clinton among satisfied Clinton voters only, indicating that the relationship between the two constructs may be complex (e.g., non- linear). For example, it is possible that voters with unfavorable attitudes toward Clinton were dissatisfied because he won, those with moderately favorable attitudes were satisfied because he won, and voters with extremely favorable attitudes towards Clinton were less satisfied because Clinton did not win by a very large margin, and in fact won with 4396 of the vote. (The press 246 and Clinton critics immediately pointed out that Clinton had not received a "mandate" from the electorate.) It is possible that the relationship between attitude and satisfaction was confounded in this context because people were voting as much against a candidate as they were for a candidate. Thus, it is possible that attitude towards a nonchoice may affect satisfaction with one's choice, and vice versa. Also, it is possible that attitudes are directly related to overall satisfaction, bypassing satisfaction with the candidate. There is some evidence this occurred. Among Bush voters, one modification index indicates model fit would be improved by adding a path from attitude towards Bush to overall satisfaction, though the path from attitude to satisfaction with Bush was not significant. The high standardized residuals associated with attitude - satisfaction covariances suggests that these relationships account for a large amount of the model's lack of fit. Finally, the simple correlations for EOSM indicate that 1) among Clinton voters, attitudes toward Bush are at least as strongly correlated with satisfaction with Clinton as are attitudes toward Clinton, 2) among Bush voters, attitudes towards Bush are nearly as highly correlated with satisfaction with Clinton as are attitudes towards Clinton, and that attitude towards Clinton and attitudes toward Bush are equally correlated with satisfaction with Bush, and 3) attitudes toward Clinton and Bush are both highly associated with overall satisfaction for Bush voters, but not for Clinton voters. Together, these results indicate the importance of measuring attitudes toward nonchoices in satisfaction research. From a managerial perspective, such a conclusion is not surprising. In many situations consumers' negative attitude towards a product or firm may play a significant, at times dominant, role in determining the choice set and/ or specific nonchoices. 247 VI-4.4. Context of the Research Though without precedent in the satisfaction literature, use of an election context for studying satisfaction has proven useful. The expected benefits of such a context (identified in Section I-S) did materialize. Specifically, variance was found in the satisfaction measures, an objective measure of performance did exist, expectations and desires were often different and could be measured on scales directly comparable with each other (and with the performance measure), "typical" antecedents of satisfaction proved to be useful, competitive dimensions of the context were clear, etc. While the study of satisfaction with the election results may or may not have inherent value to political marketers, its value for theory-testing appears clear. An important next step is to extend the analysis conducted here into a more traditional marketing context to begin to establish the external validity of key findings. First, situations which share certain competitive characteristics with an election should be studied. For example, sports event marketing or competitive bid situations in industrial marketing would be logical next contexts for studying post-purchase satisfaction formation processes. In both cases, competitive elements are obvious, choice sets are clear and known in advance, there is an objective measure of performance, pre-choice processing is likely to be widespread, and involvement is likely to be high. Assuming it is demonstrated that multiple targets and interrelated processes do operate in these more traditional contexts, the analysis could be extended further. For example, typical consumer goods could be studied. As long as nonchoices remain salient postchoice for any important consumer segment, the competitive model of satisfaction formation could be utilized. 248 VI-S. Limitations There are several limitations to the work presented here. While most are the result of conscious trade-offs, and thus are balanced by associated strengths, it is worthwhile to enumerate the most significant of these limitations. limitations fall roughly into three categories: limitations due to the research context, theoretical limitations, and methodological limitations. Each will be briefly addressed. Limitations Due to Context First, the context of a political election may involve process and dynamics very different from those found in more traditional marketing contexts. While high external context validity is not critical to the basic theoretical contributions of this dissertation, the non-traditional context does limit direct extrapolation of research findings to other contexts. Theoretical Limitations First, this dissertation does not attempt to resolve, or even address, the important conceptual or operationalization problems associated with any individual construct. Thus, it is subject to all the criticisms regarding construct validity found in the rest of the satisfaction literature. For example, the EOSM and CPSM models utilized the most common conceptualization of disconfirmation: subjective appraisal of the disconfirmation of predictive expectations. In Section [1.3.5, the criticisms of this variable were discussed in detail. Disconfirmation was operationalized as it was in this study to facilitate comparison with previous research, though an alternative comparison 249 standard may have been more appropriate. Clearly this construct did not effectively mediate the effects of desires, as well as a desires congruency measure may have been able to. Second, and more important, is the potential limitation resulting from the omission of other possible antecedent variables. Omission of antecedent variables from the EOSM, especially those which might logically be uncorrelated with satisfaction with Bush or satisfaction with Clinton, could result in model misspecification. For example, in an election context, the quality of information about each candidate could affect expectations and disconfirmation, and voters' satisfaction with information could also affect overall satisfaction (as demonstrated by Spreng 1992). Similarly, the recent intense interest in the role of affect on satisfaction formation (e.g., Westbrook and Oliver 1991; Mano and Oliver 1993; Oliver 1993) indicates that affect can have a powerful and unique effect on satisfaction formation; such potentially important antecedent variables were not included in this analysis. Methodological Limitations First, the field setting of the research made it impossible to tightly control for competing explanations of findings. This limitation affects all field studies to varying degrees. Given that this dissertation represents a first attempt at specifying the basic structure of a new model, it is impossible to evaluate the potential consequences of this limitation. Second, the sample was not randomly selected from the general population. Again, this limitation is related to the external validity of research results. While convenience sampling is often accepted as adequate for theory development and theory testing (Calder, Phillips and Tybout 1981), non- 250 probability sampling schemes inhibit the generalizability of research findings beyond a particular sample. In this research, even though attempts were made to collect a sample which mirrored the electorate, inferences beyond the sample should be made cautiously. Third, use of single item constructs poses a limitation in that measurement error cannot be estimated. One possible consequence is that path estimates are less accurate than they would be had it been possible to estimate measurement error. The repeated calls for additional research and replicating key findings in more traditional marketing settings were motivated, in part, by these limitations. VI-6. Concluding Remarks The competitive model of satisfaction is based on the idea that alternatives considered during the decision-making process of choosing remain salient beyond the choice. Extending the explicit consideration of competition from decision-making processes, with its extensive theoretical and empirical literature to post-purchase processes, will help tie together the entire consumption process. While the "emerging dialectic" of buying and consuming (Oliver and Westbrook 1991) may yield useful micro-analytic insights into bits of consumer behavior, it seems critical to remember that the entire process of buying and consuming is ongoing and at least somewhat repetitive with choice processes flowing into post-purchase processes flowing into future choice processes, etc. This dynamic process perspective has begun 251 to receive attention in the literature (e.g., Boulding et a1 1993), but certainly needs development. Further, the potential contributions of this perspective to the emerging focus on relationship marketing is clear. As firms seek to establish ongoing relationships with their consumers, the firms are really trying to eliminate other products/ services from consumer choice sets and to remain the only salient target postchoice. Within the firm, the roles of "marketing manager" and "customer service manager" are becoming blurred. For firms trying to attract consumers from a competitor, knowledge of how customers form satisfaction/ dissatisfaction becomes just as valuable as how consumers make their choices in the first place, because in relationship marketing, the two blend together. Previously, tools for investigating the competitive nature of post-purchase processes did not exist in the satisfaction literature. Given the trends towards forging long-term ties with customers, such tools are bound to become important for both theoretical and managerial analyses. LIST OF REFERENCES LIST OF REFERENCES Albrecht, Karl and Ron Zemke (1985), Service America! Doing Business in the New Economy, Homewood, IL: Dow-Jones-Irwin. Alderson, Wroe (1957), Marketing Behavior and Executive Action, Homewood, 11; Richard D. Irwin. Anderson, Ralph E. (1973), "Consumer Dissatisfaction: The Effect of Disconfirmed Expectancy on Perceived Product Performance," journal of Marketing Research, 10:1 (February), 38—44. Anderson, Eugene W. and Mary W. Sullivan (1993), "The Antecedents and Consequences of Customer Satisfaction for Firms," Marketing Science, 12:2, 125-143. Arnould, Eric J. and Linda 1.. Price (1993), "River Magic: Extraordinary Experience and the Extended Service Encounter," Journal of Consumer Research, 20: 1, 24—45. Babin, Barry J., Mitch Griffin, and William R. Darden (in press), "An Empirical Comparison of Alternative Conceptualizations of Postconsumption Reactions," Journal of Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction and Complaining Behavior. Barbeau, J. Bradley (1984), "Predictive and Normative Expectations in Consumer Satisfaction: A Utilization of Adaption and Comparison Levels in a Unified Framework, " in Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction, and Complaining Behavior Conference Proceedings, 27-32. Bearden, William D. and Jesse E. Teel (1983), "Selected Determinants of Consumer Satisfaction and Complaint Reports," Journal of Marketing Research, 20:4 (November), 21-28. Bitner, Mary Jo (1990), "Evaluating Service Encounters: The Effect of Physical Surroundings and Employee Responses," Journal of Marketing, 54 (April): 69-82. Bitner, Mary Jo, and Amy R. Hubbert (1994), "Encounter Satisfaction Versus Overall Satisfaction Versus Quality," in Service Quality: New Directions in Theory and Practice, edited by Roland T. Rust and Richard L. Oliver, Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications, Inc. Bolfing, Claire P. and Robert B. Woodruff (1988), "Effects of Situational Involvement on Consumers' Use of Standards in Satisfaction/ Dissatisfaction Processes," Journal of Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction and Complaining Behavior, 1, 16-24. 252 253 Boulding, William, Ajay Kalra, Richard Staelin, and Valerie A. Zeithaml (1993), "A Dynamic Process Model of Service Quality: From Expectations to Behavioral Intentions," Journal of Marketing Research, 30:1,7-27. Brown, Stephen W. and Teresa A. Swartz (1989), "A Gap Analysis of Professional Service Quality," Journal of Marketing, 53:2(April), 92-98. Cadotte, Ernest R., Robert B. Woodruff, Roger L. Jenkins (1987), "Expectations and Norms in Models of Consumer Satisfaction," Journal of Marketing Research, 24:3, 305-3 14. Calder, Bobby J., Lynn W. Phillips, and Alice M. Tybout (1981), "Designing Research for Application," Journal of Consumer Research, 8:2,197-207. Cardozo, Richard, N. (1965), "An Experimental Study of Customer Effort, Expectation and Satisfaction," Journal of Marketing Research, 2:3 (August), 224-229. Churchill, Gilbert A., Jr., and Carol Surprenant (1982), "An Investigation into the Determinants of Consumer Satisfaction," Journal of Marketing Research, 19:4 (November), 491-504. Churchill, Gilbert A., Jr. (1983), Marketing Research--Methodological Foundations, Chicago, IL: The Dryden Press. Cooper, Ann R., M. Bixby Cooper, and Dale F. Duhan (1989), "Measurement Instrument Developed Using Two Competing Concepts of Customer Satisfaction," Journal of Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction and Complaining Behavior, Volume 2, 28-35. Cronin, Joseph J. and Steven A. Taylor (1992), "Measuring Service Quality: A Reexamination and Extension," Journal of Marketing, 56:3,55-68. Czepiel, John A. and Larry J. Rosenberg (1977), "Customer Satisfaction: Concept and Measurement," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 5:4 (Fall), 403-41 1. Day, Ralph L. (1984), "Modeling Choices Among Alternative Responses to Dissatisfaction," in Advances in Consumer Research, Vol. 11, Thomas C. Kinnear, ed. Ann Arbor, MI: Association of Consumer Research, 496-499. Droge, Cornelia, and Diane Halstead (1991),"Postpurchase Hierarchies of Effects: The Antecedents and Consequences of Satisfaction for Complainers versus Non-complainers," International Journal of Research in Marketing, 8:4(November), 315-328. Duhaime, Carole P. (1988), "Consumer Satisfaction with the Distribution System for Durable Products," Journal of Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction, and Complaining Behavior, 1, 53-59. Engel, James R, David J. Kollet, and Roger D. Blackwell (1973), Consumer Behavior, Hinsdale, IL: Dryden. 254 Festinger, Leon (1957), A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Fishbein, Martin (1967), "Attitude and the Prediction of Behavior," in Readings in Attitude Theory and Measurement, M. Fishbein, ed., NY: John Wiley, 477-492 Fisk, Raymond P., and Clifford E. Young (1985), "Disconfirmation of Equity Expectations: Effects on Consumer Satisfaction with Services," in Advances in Consumer Research, E. Hirschman and H. Holbrook, eds., Provo, UT: Association for Consumer Research. Fornell, Claes (1992), "A National Customer Satisfaction Barometer: The Swedish Experience," Journal of Marketing, 56:1,6-21. Gardial, Sarah Fisher, D. Scott Clemons, Robert B. Woodruff, David W. Schumann, and Mary Jane Burns (1994), "Comparing Consumers' Recall of Prepurchase and Postpurchase Product Evaluation Experiences," Journal of Consumer Research, 20 (March), 548-560. Garland, Barbara C. and Robert A. Westbrook (1989) "An Exploration of Client Satisfaction in a Nonprofit Context."Journal of the Academy of Marketing Sciences, 17:4, 297-303. Granbois, Donald, John O. Summers, and Gary l. Frazier (1977), "Correlates of Consumer Expectations and Complaining Behavior," in Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction, and Complaining Behavior, Proceedings of the Second Annual CS/D&CB conference, ed. Ralph Day, 18-25. Halstead, Diane (1992), "The Expectations-Satisfaction Relationship Revisited: An Empirical Test and Directions for Future Research," in Proceedings of the 1 992 AMA Winter Educa tors' Conference. Herzberg, Frederick, B. Mausner, and B. Snyderman (1959), The Motivation to Work, New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Holbrook, Morris B., and Elizabeth C. Hirshman (1982), "The Experiential Aspects of Consumption: Consumer Fantasies, Feelings, and Fun," The Journal of Consumer Research, 9:2,132-140. Houston, David A., Steven J. Sherman, and Sara M. Baker (1991), "Feature Matching, Unique Features, and the Dynamics of the Choice Process: Predecision Conflict and Postdecision Satisfaction," Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 27:5, 41 1-430. Howard, John A., and Jagdish N. Sheth (1969), The Theory of Buyer Behavior, New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons. Hunt, H. Keith (1977), Customer Satisfaction and Dissatisfaction: Perspectives and Overview, Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute (Report No. 77- 112). 255 Hunt, Shelby D. (1991), Modern Marketing Theory - Critical Issues in the Philosophy of Marketing Science, Cincinnati, OH: South-Western Publishing Co. Izard, C. E. (1984), "Emotion-Cognition Relationships and Human Development," in C. E. Izard, J. Kagan, and R. B. Zajonc, eds., Emotion, Cognition, and Behavior, New York: Cambridge University Press. Jereskog, Karl G. and Dag Sbrbom (1989), LISREL 7 - A Guide to the Program and Applications, second edition, Chicago, Il: SPSS Inc. Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky (1979), "Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision Under Risk," Econometrica, 47, 952-963. Katona, G. (1964), The Mass Consumption Society, NY: McGraw Hill. Kennedy, John R., and Peter C. Thirkell (1988), "An Extended Perspective on the Antecedents of Satisfaction, " Journal of Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction and Complaining Behavior, 1, 2-10. Kerlinger, Fred, N. (1986), Foundations of Behavioral Research, Third Edition, Fort Worth, TX: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, Inc. Kotler, Philip (1980), Marketing Managemen t--Analysis, Planning and Control, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. LaBarberra, Priscilla, and David Mazursky (1983), "A Longitudinal Assessment of Consumer Satisfaction/ Dissatisfaction: The Dynamic Aspect of the Cognitive Process," Journal of Marketing Research, 20:9,393-404. LaTour, Stephen A. and Nancy C. Peat (1979), "Conceptual and Methodological Issues in Consumer Satisfaction Research," in Advances in Consumer Research, Vol. 6, William L. Wilkie, ed. Ann Arbor, MI: Association for Consumer Research, 43 1-43 7. Lazarus, R. S. (1984), "On the Primacy of Cognition," American Psychologist, 39, 124-129. Lele, Milind M., and Jagdish N. Sheth (1987), The Customer is Key, New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons. Loomes, Graham, and Robert Sugden (1982), "Regret Theory: An Alternative Theory of Rational Choice Under Uncertainty," The Economic Journal, 92 (December), 805-824. Lord, Frederick M. (1963), "Elementary Models for Measuring Change," in C. W. Harris, ed., Problems in Measuring Change, Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press. Maddox, R. Neil (1981), "Two-Factor Theory and Consumer Satisfaction: Replication and Extension," Journal of Consumer Research, 8:1,97-102. 256 Mano, Haim, and Richard L. Oliver (1993), "Assessing the Dimensionality and Structure of the Consumption Experience: Evaluation, Feeling, and Satisfaction," Journal of Consumer Research, 20 (December). Miller, John A. (1977), "Studying Satisfaction, Modifying Models, Eliciting Expectations, Posing Problems, and Making Meaningful Measurements," in Conceptualiza tion and Measurement of Consumer Satisfaction and Dissatisfaction, H. K Hunt, ed. Mizerski, Richard W. (1982), "An Attribution Explanation of Disproportionate Influence of Unfavorable Information," Journal of Consumer Research, 9 (December), 301-308. Nystrom, Paul H. (1929), The Economic Principles of Consumption, The Ronald Press Co. Oliver, Richard L (1980), "A Cognitive Model of the Antecedents and Consequences of Satisfaction Decisions," Journal of Marketing Research, 17:4 (November), 460-469. Oliver, Richard L. (1981), "Measurement and Evaluation of Satisfaction Processes in Retail Settings," Journal of Retailing, 57:3 (Fall), 25-48. Oliver, Richard L. (1993), "Cognitive, Affective, and Attribute Bases of the Satisfaction Response," Journal of Consumer Research, 20 (December). - Oliver, Richard L. and William O. Bearden (1983), "The Role of Involvement in Satisfaction Processes," in Advances in Consumer Research, Volume 10, eds. Richard P. Bagozzi and Alice M. Tybout, Ann Arbor, MI: Association for Consumer Research, 250-255. Oliver, Richard L. and William O. Bearden ( 1985), "Disconfirmation Processes and Consumer Evaluations in Product Usage," Journal of Business Research, 13:2,235-246. Oliver, Richard L. and Wayne S. DeSarbo (1988), "Response Determinants in Satisfaction Judgments," Journal of Consumer Research, 14:4 (December), 372- 383. Oliver, Richard L. and Gerald Linda (1981), "Effect of Satisfaction and Its Antecedents on Consumer Preference and Intention," in Advances in Consumer Research, Volume 8, Kent Monroe, ed., Ann Arbor, MI: Association for Consumer Research. Oliver, Richard L. and John E. Swan (1989), "Equity and Disconfirmation Perceptions as Influences on Merchant and Product Satisfaction," Journal of Consumer Research, 16:4 (December), 372-3 83. Olshavsky, Richard W. and John A. Miller (1972), "Consumer Expectation, Product Performance and Perceived Product Quality," Journal of Marketing Research, 9:1 (February), 19-21. 257 Olson, Jerry C., and Philip A. Dover (1979), "Disconfirmation of Consumer Expectations Through Product Trial," Journal of Applied Psychology, 64:2,179- 189. Parasuraman, A., Valerie A. Zeithaml, and Leonard 1.. Berry (1988), "SERVQUAI: A Multi-Item Scale for Measuring Consumer Perceptions of Service Quality," Journal of Retailing, 64:1, 12-40. Patterson, Paul G. (1993), "Expectations and Product Performance as Determinants of Satisfaction for a High-Involvement Purchase," Psychology and Marketing, 10:5,449-465. Peter, J. Paul, Gilbert A. Churchill, Jr., and Tom J. Brown (1993), "Caution in the Use of Difference Scores in Consumer Research," Journal of Consumer Research, 19 (March), 655-662. Peterson, Robert A. and William R. Wilson (1992), "Measuring Customer Satisfaction: Fact and Artifact," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 20:1,61-71. Petty, Richard E., and John T. Cacioppo (1986), "The Elaboration likelihood Model of Persuasion," in Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, Vol. 19, edited by L. Berkowitz, FL: Academic Press, 123-205. Prakash, Ved and John W. Lounsbury (1984), "The Role of Expectations in the Determination of Consumer Satisfaction," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 12:3 (Summer), 1-17. Reichheld, Frederick F. and W. Earl Sasser, Jr. (1990) "Zero Defections: Quality Comes to Services," Harvard Business Review, 68:5 (September-October): 105- 111. Richins, Marsha L. (1983), "Negative Word-of-Mouth by Dissatisfied Consumers: A Pilot Study," Journal of Marketing, 47 (Winter), 68-78. Richins, Marsha L. and Peter H. Bloch (1991), "Post-Purchase Product Satisfaction: Incorporating the Effects of Involvement and Time," Journal of Business Research, 23:2, 145-158. Sherif, M., and C. I. Hovland (1961), Social Judgment: Assimilation and Contrast Effects in Communication and Attitude Change, New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Sheth, Jagdish M., David M. Gardner, and Dennis E. Garrett (1988), Marketing Theory: Evolution and Evaluation, New York: John Wiley & Sons. Singh, Jagdip (1991) "Understanding the Structure of Consumers' Satisfaction Evaluations of Service Delivery," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 19:3 (Summer): 223-244. Sirgy, Joseph M. (1984), "A Social Cognition Model of Consumer Satisfaction/ Dissatisfaction," Psychology and Marketing, 1:2,27—43. 258 Spreng, Richard A (1992), A Comprehensive Model of the Consumer Satisfaction Formation Process, unpublished doctoral dissertation, University of Indiana. Spreng, Richard A., Andrea L Dixon, and Richard W. Olshavsky (1993), "The Impact of Value Judgments on Consumer Satisfaction," Journal of Consumer Satisfaction, Dissatisfaction, and Complaining Behavior, in press. Spreng, Richard A. and Andrea L. Dixon (1992), "Alternative Comparison Standards in the Formation of Consumer Satisfaction/ Dissatisfaction," Enhancing Knowledge Development in Marketing, 1989 Educators' Proceedings, Chicago, IL: American Marketing Association. Spreng, Richard A., and Richard W. Olshavsky (1993), "A Desires Congruency Model of Consumer Satisfaction," Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 21:3, 169-178. Swan, John E. and linda J. Combs (1976), "Product Performance and Consumer Satisfaction: A New Concept," Journal of Marketing, 40:2, 25-33. Swan, John E. and Warren S. Martin (1981), "Testing Comparison Level and Predictive Expectations Models of Satisfaction, " in Advances in Consumer Research, Volume 8, Kent Monroe, ed., Ann Arbor, MI: Association for Consumer Research, 77-82. Swan, John E. and 1. Frederick Trawick (1981), "Disconfirmation of Expectations and Satisfaction with a Retail Service," Journal of Retailing, 57:3 (Fall), 49-67. Tichy, Noel M. and Stratford Sherman (1993), "Jack Welch's Lessons for Success," Fortune, 127:2, 86-93. Tse, David K. and Peter C. Wilton (1988), "Models of Consumer Satisfaction Formation: An Extension," Journal of Marketing Research, 25:2 (May), 204-212. Westbrook, Robert A. (1980), "Intrapersonal Affective Influences Upon Consumer Satisfaction with Products," Journal of Consumer Research, 7:4, 49- S4. Westbrook, Robert A. and Joseph W. Newman (1978), "An Analysis of Shopper Dissatisfaction for Major Household Appliances," Journal of Marketing Research, 15:3, 456-466. Westbrook, Robert A. and Richard 1.. Oliver (1991), "The Dimensionality of Consumption Emotion Patterns and Consumer Satisfaction," Journal of Consumer Research, 18: 1, 84-9 1. Westbrook, Robert A., and Michael K. Reilly (1983), "Value-Percept Disparity: An Alternative to the Disconfirmation of Expectations Theory of Consumer Satisfaction," in Advances in Consumer Research, Volume 10, eds. Richard P. Bagozzi and Alice M. Tybout, Ann Arbor, MI: Association for Consumer Research, 256-261. 259 Woodruff, Robert B., Ernest R. Cadotte, and Roger L. Jenkins (1983), "Modeling consumer Satisfaction Processes Using Experience-Based Norms," Journal of Marketing Research, 20:3 (August), 296-304. Yi, Youjae (1990), "A Critical Review of Consumer Satisfaction," in Review of Marketing 1990, edited by Valarie A. Zeithaml, Chicago, IL: American Marketing Association. Zajonc, R. B. (1980), "Feeling and Thinking: Preferences Need No Inferences," American Psychologist, 35, 15 1-175. Zajonc, R. B. (1984), "On the Primacy of Affect," American Psychologist,39:2, 117-123. Zaichowsky, Judith Lynn (1985), "Measuring the Involvement Construct," Journal of Consumer Research, 12 (December), 341-352. Ill/ills mil 61766 I v ’1'! I 1” I; U H E II 0104 I! l I l! I] (I TI I I 1’ I I I (I I! 1’ I i I I. I 31293 ill!