ABSTRACT ELITE RECRUITMENT IN EASTERN EUROPE: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS BY Gary C. Shaw Elite studies of Western industrialized societies emphasize the increasing importance of technical expertise as a variable influencing recruitment to elite positions. Recent studies of elite recruitment in the USSR reveal the same trends at work there. The purpose of this study is to examine and compare elite recruitment trends in four Eastern European countries to determine if similar forces are present there and to compare the responses of different communist parties to changes in skill requirements. All the parties considered in this study—-the Bulgarian, the Czechoslovakian, the Hungarian, and the Polish—-have publicly recognized some of the shortcomings of their economic systems and have made commitments to economic reform. These commitments should be reflected in elite recruitment patterns. The study, which focused on the Central Committees and the Politburos, covered the 1957 to 1968 period. Gary C. Shaw Data for the study came primarily from two sources. The archive on Eastern European elites at the University of Pittsburg provided data for the 1957 to 1964 period. The author added data from the Radio Free Europe research de- partments to make the study as current as possible (1966 for the Central Committees, 1968 for the Politburos). Indepen— dent variables included: career patterns, skill attributes, education level, education area, age, penultimate office, ethnicity, father's occupation, revolutionary experience, and economic characteristics of place of birth. The major hypothesis of the study was that the data would reveal an increase in recruitment of elites with technical skills. Minor hypotheses were, first, the data would reveal an in- crease in recruitment of non-political professionals and, second, oligarchy, in communist societies, does not tend to age. The major hypothesis was substantiated. Recruitment trends reveal an appreciable increase in elites with techni- cal skills. However, each country reSponded differently to this change in skill requirements. Bulgaria experienced a significant increase in recruitment of non—political profes- sionals but the other countries changed very little in this regard. Data on age indicate that communist elites are "able to impose their young upon the party." Gary C. Shaw Each country in the study revealed a distinct devel- opmental pattern. The structure of opportunities for elite positions in each party was altered from 1957 to 1968, reflecting changes in skill requirements. The manner in which each recruitment system reSponded to these changes was determined by social, economic, and political forces at work in the country. The data revealed positive trends in coop- tation of elites with rational-technical skills, but they also revealed that, in spite of fairly obvious economic imperatives, the strong role of ideology and politics fre— quently interrupts and often upsets trends that might be imputed to the need for economic rationalization. ELITE RECRUITMENT IN EASTERN EUROPE: A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS By _\ .\‘ Gary C: Shaw A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science 1970 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I am particularly grateful to the members of my guidance committee for their assistance during the prepara— tion and writing of this thesis. Dr. Thomas Greene not only made a significant contribution to my thesis but also pro- vided much of the intellectual stimulation for my entire graduate program. Dr. Ellen Mickiewicz provided some in- valuable insights on the focus of my research and also pointed out some rather glaring mistakes in the body of my thesis. Dr. Tim Hennessey contributed to the research design and helped me solve the methodological problems. Tom McClure and Elizabeth Powell, working in the department data archive, provided not a little greatly needed and greatly appreciated assistance with my data. Liz, who has similar research interests, lent a sympathetic ear to my problems and offered some useful insights from her own research experience. My greatest debt, however, is owed to my parents, who provided meaningful stimulation and cheerfully made sacrifices in my behalf, and to my wife, Kathy, who made it all worthwhile. It is to them that I gratefully dedicate this thesis. ii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page ACKNOWLEDGMENTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii LIST OF TABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . v LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vii CHAPTER I. INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . l The Comparative Study of Communist Political Systems The Study of Elites Elite Recruitment in Eastern Europe Methodology Independent variables II. POLITICAL DEVELOPMENT IN EASTERN EUROPE . . . . 27 Economic Development in Eastern Europe Economic Development and Political Change Summary III. THE CENTRAL COMMITTEE . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 Background variables Ethnicity Career Characteristics Career Patterns Age Revolutionary Activity Career Paths for Minority Groups Summary IV. THE POLITBURO . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87 Background Characteristics Ethnicity Career Characteristics Career Patterns Age Revolutionary Activity Summary iii CHAPTER Page V. CONCLUSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111 Elite Recruitment and Economic Change The Comparative Study of Elites Prospects for Future Research BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126 iv Table 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. LIST OF TABLES Growth of GNP, Prewar to 1964 (Annual Percentage Increases) . . . . . . . . . . . Growth of Personal Consumption in Relation to GNP (Ratios of Growth Rates, in Percent). Comparative Level of Personal Consumption Per capita O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 Social Background Characteristics of Central Committee Members (In Percent) . . . . . . . Representation of Minority Groups in Central Committees (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . Participation in Revolutionary Activity for Ethnic Groups in Eastern Europe . . . . Formal Education of Ethnic Groups in the Central Committee, KSC (In Percent) . . . Education Level of Central Committee Members (In Percent) O O O O O O O O 0 O O O O O O 0 Education Area or Training (In Percent) . . Skill Characteristics of Central Committee Members (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . . . . Career Patterns for Central Committee Members (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Education Area of Party Bureaucrats (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Penultimate Office for Central Committee Members (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . . Mean Age of Central Committee Members Mean Age at Cooptation . . . . . . . . . . . . Page 32 34 34 52 55 56 57 58 59 61 66 67 7O 72 73 Table 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. 31. Page Deviations from the Mean——Career and Skill Categories, 1966 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77 Participation in Revolutionary Activity (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78 Changes in Composition--Central Committee . . . 82 Contingency Coefficients for Selected variables. 84 Social Background Characteristics of Politburo Members and Candidates (In Percent). . . . . . 90 Ethnic Composition of East European Politburos . 92 Education Level of Politburo Members and Candidates (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . . . 94 Education Area for Politburo Members with High Educations (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . . . 94 Education Area for Politburo Members and Candidates (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . . . 95 Skill Characteristics of Politburo Members and Candidates (In Percent) . . . . . . . . , 95 Career Characteristics of Politburo Members and Candidates (In Percent) . . . . . . . . . 98 Mean Age of Politburo Members and Candidates . . 99 Mean Age at Cooptation for Politburo Members and Candidates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102 Revolutionary Activity Relevant (In Percent) . . 103 Changes in Composition--Politburo . . . . . . . 105 Significance Levels for x2 Tests (Drops and Adds Only) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106 vi LIST OF FIGURES Figure Page 1. Recruits and Members Possessing Technical Skills 0 I 0 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O o 62 2. Recruits and Members Possessing Control Skills . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 3. Mean Ages of Central Committee Members, 1957 . . 74 4. Mean Ages of Central Committee Members, 1966 . . 75 5. Mean Ages of Politburo Members and Candidates, 1957 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100 6. Mean Ages of Politburo Members and Candidates, 1968 O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O O 0 O O 101 vii CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION The Comparative Study of Communist Political Systems Students of comparative politics have only recently deve10ped the requisite theoretical and methodological s0phistication for a truly comparative approach to the study of political phenomena. Unfortunately, this development has been quite uneven-—most of the significant studies to date have concentrated on the Western democracies.1 Students of communist political systems, strongly influenced by the totalitarian "paradigm," have been conSpicuous in their failure to develop comparative approaches applicable to these systems.2 Recent trends in studies of communism reflect a growing awareness of the inadequacy of existing conceptual tools. This is, perhaps, an inevitable consequence of the "behavioral mentality," but it does indicate that scholars now recognize that communism is not an aberration but a very real alternative to the Western model of industrialization. It also reflects growing disenchantment with the totali— tarian model. Communism is not a monolith; it is as diverse 2 in its political manifestations as democracy and certainly as difficult to conceptualize and analyze. One of the major problems facing students of commu- nist political systems is that of obtaining reliable data. This is particularly true of ruling parties, most of which have not been accessible to most forms of analysis. (Non- ruling parties can be penetrated, however, and are proving to be fruitful sources of data and theory.)3 The data that have become available illustrate manifestations of pluralism or potential pluralism. Studies of decision-making in the USSR, for example, have revealed the conflicts inherent in the "bureaucratic system"--conflicts which are also present in other European communist systems but which have been modi— fied and intensified by particular cultural and ethnic char- acteristics.4 Ghita Ionescu has developed a useful approach for classifying the kinds of tensions that increase cultural pluralism.5 Richard Burks is very successful in isolating the ethnic groups which communism appealed to in the inter— war period and which provided the leadership for native com- munist movements.6 Dominant ethnic groups now control the Party in each of the Eastern European countries, but ethnic conflicts are still very salient in some areas as recent events in Czechoslovakia and Rumania illustrate. Burks and Ionescu both isolate variables which can be defined, quantified, and compared cross-nationally. This is the direction in which studies of communism must now move. Paul Shoup, in a very useful bibliographical essay discussing 3 prOSpects for an empirical approach to communism, states that "the theoretical and methodological problems that must be overcome in developing a new field of comparative studies range over a wide area, from the development of typologies and dynamic concepts of evolution and change to the problem of gathering data and applying quantitative comparative techniques."7 Alfred Meyer,8 taking a slightly different approach, concludes that students of communism could benefit from analyzing communism in the context of frameworks already developed for studying non-communist systems, e.g., the bureaucratic model.9 Other useful discussions of cur- rent methodological problems in comparative communism include Skilling, "Interest Groups and Communist Politics,"10 and "Soviet and Communist Politics: A Comparative Approach,"11 and TUCker, "On the Comparative Study of Communism."12 Richard Cornell, concentrating primarily on approaches for studying non-ruling parties, elaborates numerous hypotheses which could be analyzed to isolate similarities and dis- similarities in patterns of development.13 Benjamin and Kautsky, conceptualizing communist movements as one variant of modernizing movements, derive measures for correlating communist party strength with level of economic develop- ment.14 Two points concerning the problems of conceptual- ization and model building are relevant. In the first place, comparison and model building need not be on a system level; indeed, until large gaps in existing data are filled, 4 specific sub-system comparisons appear to be the most fruitful level (e.g., elite stratification, levels of economic decision-making, role of the media, and so forth). A general theory of communism, though certainly a desirable end, will require a great deal of spade work if it is to be meaningful. Secondly, existing conceptual frameworks can usefully be applied to communist systems (e.g., structural functional analysis, systems analysis, decision-making theory, bureaucratic models, developmental typologies, elite- stratification models);15 it is not necessary to develop whole new sets of theories or models to analyze and explain behavior in these systems although innovations certainly will be required. Even the totalitarian model, if used as an ideal type and not an empirical reality, can be employed profitably. This raises a final problem relevant to the concern with conceptualization, developing typologies and model building. Duverger summed it up nicely almost two decades ago: "A general theory of parties will eventually be con— structed only upon the preliminary work of many profound studies, but these studies cannot be truly profound so long as there exists no general theory of parties."16 This prob- lem is exemplified today in conflicts between area Special- ists and theory oriented generalists. Generalists assert that area Specialists cannot be effective social scientists unless they utilize theoretical frameworks and techniques associated with behavioral research. Area specialists 5 counter this attack with the effective argument that empirical studies must be grounded on an understanding of the social forces operating in a given country to make research meaningful. The necessity of an empirical approach to political science in general and communist studies in particular has been accepted by most competent scholars. The second prob- lem remains, however. How can generalists purport to make contributions toward an understanding of political behavior. without substantial grounding in area Specialization? Frederic J. Fleron, in discussing this problem, concludes that the determining factor becomes the "realm of inquiry" in which one is operating.17 He distinguishes between a context of discovery and a context of verification. If the student were operating in the context of verification a knowledge of culture and history would not be necessary. "The generalizations to be tested would already hypothesize which cultural and historical variables are relevant, and these are the only aSpectS of Russian culture and history which need to be known for the purpose of confirming or dis- comfirming those generalizations."18 If the student were operating in the realm of discovery, however, presumably he would not know which cultural and historical variables were relevant to a given hypothesis and would have to "immerse" himself in cultural and historical studies. Conceptualization of the problem and the research strategy chosen become, in lieu of area Specialization, crucial variables in determining 6 the validity of a general theoretical approach to research. The important point is that hypothesis testing and theory building can proceed without a complete groundwork of area Specialization studies if scholars are competent methodolo- gists. The Study of Elites Elite recruitment has long been recognized as one of the crucial variables affecting the style and substance of politics. Two variables relating to political leader- ship--the representativeness of elites and the manner of their selection--are important not only for an understanding of political events but also for analysis of the dynamic of the entire social system. The elite dimension, as Lasswell indicates, is always relevant--whether one is seeking to explain the past or present or predict the future, whether a question of trend, condition, projection, goal of alterna- tive.19 An evaluation of elite recruitment patterns provides a key means of entry into every political system. Elite analyses of pre and post World War 11 Germany, for example, have made a significant contribution to our understanding of the phenomenon of fascism.20 Elite studies of Western societies have tradition- ally faced two conceptual problems: definition of elites and the development of satisfactory stratification models. These problems are exemplified in the Hunter-Dahl diSpute which has plagued students of government in the United States. 7 In Spite of the conceptual problems posed by "pluralist" societies, some very useful theoreticalz1 and empirical22 studies of elites in industrialized societies have been published recently. One of the goals of this study will be to test some of the empirical findings and hypotheses of these studies using data on East European elites. It may be possible to find some significant similarities between "capitalist" industrialized societies and communist indus- trializing societies in terms of stratification and recruit- ment of elites. Although the studies mentioned above differ in terms of conceptualization of elite status and develop different kinds of stratification models, they are generally agreed upon the very crucial role expertise is assuming as a gov- erning norm in elite recruitment. There is also a general agreement as to the kinds of variables which can be analyzed profitably. These include, for example, development of recruitment patterns, circulation of elites, skill and resources either required or possessed by elites, social origins, goals and interests, beliefs and styles of action, governing norms, perceptions of self and others, ethnicity, the role of external elites, and so forth. Students of communist political systems are obviously limited in the kinds of analyses they can make. Many of the variables mentioned above cannot be empirically tested in authoritarian regimes. The totalitarian model militates against process oriented studies of communist societies.23 8 Despite recent changes in the structure of decision-making in these societies, few would argue that it is now possible to analyze patterns of interaction and conflict. We can begin to make inroads into these elite structures, however. Sufficient information is available to discuss recruitment patterns for higher positions, circulation, functional requisites, demographic attributes, and Skill and resource requirements. Crucial questions remain, however; we have very little information concerning governing norms, goals, the relationship between values and background, and the in— ternal decision-making process. A few Significant studies of communist elites have been published. These have generally been either studies of particular leaders (usually revolutionaries) or analyses of specific sub-groups.24 Theoretically oriented studies of communist elites have emerged only in the last few years.25 The present study will be a comparative analysis of two Specific sub-groups in four East European countries-- Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland. The sub- groups to be examined are the Politburos and Central Com- mittees for each of these countries. Elite status will be defined as holding, or having held, a position in one of these two offices. This functional institutional definition of elites will avoid some of the problems of conceptualiza- tion mentioned above.26 The assumption is being made that the "influentials," the "strategic elites," the "power elites," if you will, are represented in these institutionally 9 defined bodies. The study will make an empirical contribu- tion to the general problem of theory building in communist studies and the more Specific task of developing models to explain elite behavior in communist societies. Elite Recruitment in Eastern Europe This research project is designed to determine "Opportunity structures" for the Central Committee and Pcilitburo in each of the countries under investigation. Jcnseph Schlesinger developed the structure of opportunities concept in a recent study of political elites in the United Stmites.27 Elite behavior, as revealed in office-seeking Sixtuations, is explained as a function of political ambition. The kind of ambition a politician has ("discrete," "static," or' "progressive") is dependent upon his reasonable chance ier success in capturing or retaining a political office-- iJi the "structure of opportunities" accompanying a given office. The structure of opportunities in any state is determined by structural characteristics, party organization and.competition, size of electorate, and the kinds of offices available. Schlesinger devoted little attention to an inves- tigation of personal attributes required for success in American politics. Ambition theory would be very difficult to use in the context of communist politics. It is possible, however, to mOdify the opportunity structure concept so as to make it a useful analytical tool. 10 Political advancement in communist states is primarily a cooptive process. This is not to deny the importance of self-selection or office seeking ambition-— tunioubtedly these play a role in determining entry into and advancement within the elite structure. An individual is seilected for a given position, however--this means that he must satisfy requirements as established by those reSponSi- 'b1<3 for that position. A basic assumption underlying this Stnidy is that political success, as measured by membership 111 a Central Committee or Politburo, is dependent upon func- tix>nal contributions to the polity. An investigation of the kiJids of individuals recruited into these bodies will reveal functional requisites as perceived by the dominant elites. I vvill be seeking to isolate and compare some of the personal atrtributes, career characteristics, and skills which are re- CDJired for recruitment. The dependent variable is membership in either the Cernmal Committee or Politburo. Independent variables are: age“ ethnicity, father's occupation, revolutionary activity, Penultimate office, Skills, and career. The study will cover a nine to fourteen year time Span depending upon the country and office. A profile of elites will be made, based on the composition of the Central Committee and Politburo 0f each of these countries at the end of the New Course Period.early in 1957.28 This will then be compared with a Profile of elites in the Central Committee in 1966, and the Politburo in 1968.29 All the individuals either recruited 11 into these bodies or dropped from them from 1957 to 1968 will also be analyzed in an attempt to isolate trends affecting recruitment. The study will allow us to determine some of the bajsic trends influencing recruitment into elite positions. WEE'will also be able to draw conclusions regarding changes 1J1 functional requisites for the society. The major hypothesis of the study is that technical elxites will become increasingly important in the decision- malcing process as communist states industrialize. Technical e];ites are defined as those elites who have had specialized txvaining in technical fields and who have spent significant portions of their careers in technical work. (This defini- tion will be elaborated below.) Two minor hypotheses will be tested also in this Sthdy. The first of these, which elaborates the major hYpothesis, is derived from two recent studies of elites in the USSR.30 Frederic Fleron constructed a typology of leadership systems based on group political participation and the utilization of skills. He elaborates and defines four types of leadership systems according to elite response to functional requisites for an industrial society: "mono- Cratic" (political elites force Specialized elites to con- tribute their skills at no cost), "adaptive monocratic" (P01itica1 elites either retrain members of the elite system CW recruit into the system as replacements those cadres with necessary skills), "cooptative" (political elites coopt into 12 the system Specialized elites who possess necessary skills), and "pluralist" (political elites Share power with Special- ized elites on a competitive basis). His examination of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union led him to conclude that thta leadership system is a cooptative System--that is, Spuecialized elites, who have already established themselves prwafessionally, are drafted into the Central Committee to ftulfill functional requisites for the society. Fischer, who analyzed Communist Party officials in the USSR on three administrative levels, developed a leader— Slrip typology based on Skills: "dual executive" (a Party Oifificial with extensive experience in both Party and tech— nixzal work), "technician" (a Party executive with extensive technical but little Party work in the economy), "hybrid executive" (Party executive with technical training but no Enrtensive work in the economy), "official" (Party executive Wisth neither technical training nor extensive work in the economy). According to Fischer's analysis the dual execu- tive type seems to be increasing in representation while the technician is decreasing in representation. In Fleron's tYpology this would indicate that the system was moving from a c00ptative system to an adaptive system. (Fischer's anal— Ysis only covers a five-year period, however, so projection 0f trends is somewhat limited.) A synthesis of these two studies suggests a minor hypothesis: analysis of recruitment in Eastern Europe will reveal a trend of increasing representation of professionals-- 13 that is, of individuals who have established themselves in certain non—party career areas. I expect this to be charac- teristic of the Central Committee but not the Politburo. Studies of Politburos in Eastern Europe and the USSR reveal a tendency of continuous over-representation of professional politicians in the Politburo given their representation on the Central Committee.31 I expect to discover two recruit- ment "systems," one increasingly stressing technical exper- tise as an important requisite and the other relying on political expertise as the primary requisite. My second minor hypothesis is very familiar: "oli- garchy tends to age." Duverger suggests a significant modi- fIleation to this assumption. Centralized parties, he claims, "32 A commu— are able to "impose their young upon the party. nist party elite has the authority to effect a relatively Significant turnover in its elite structure, particularly at lower levels. I expect to find that Central Committees and Politburos again will differ in this respect with Central Committees being relatively stable in terms of age of members 01‘ possibly even declining in mean age as old party function— aries are replaced by younger, technically oriented elites. In addition to these hypotheses the findings of some earlier studies (e.g., Burks' conclusions regarding the relationship between communism and ethnicity in the inter and post World War II period) will be analyzed. This will enable us to confirm or modify earlier trends in composition 14 of ruling bodies as the party moves from non—ruling to ruling status. Finally, one of the basic criticisms of students of cxnmmunism has been their failure to attempt to bridge the gap between their findings and the information we already lurve concerning political behavior in Western industrial- izing societies. In my concluding chapter I will attempt to aruilyze some conclusions and hypotheses from elite studies of? non-communist societies on the basis of my findings in tlris study. I have selected, after examining elite studies b3? Keller, Lasswell, Knight, Duverger, Matthews, Bottomore, arrd.Edinger, six hypotheses about elites in Western socie- thaS‘WhiCh can be discussed with the findings from this Study.33 1. Everywhere careers are lengthened, with success coming only after years of work in Specialized fields. 2. The "structure of opportunities" will be dif- ferent for minority groups. 3. Members of the elite strata are becoming older at success. 4. The elite Opportunity structure can be described as having a number of peaks; each scalable by Specialized methods. 5. The trends toward expansion and Specialization will be manifest in all elite pyramids. 6. Bureaucratic elites will gain dominance over political elites because of Specialization. 15 Methodology Most of the data for this study came from Carl Beck's aanzhive at the University of Pittsburg. Beck has collected Inisic demographic and career information for all the indi- vixiuals serving on the Central Committees, Politburos, Senzretariats, and Councils of Ministers of Bulgaria, Czecho- SJJovakia, Hungary, Poland, and Rumania from 1945 to 1965. (131e data on the Central Committee of Rumania are incomplete, hcnwever, and for this reason I have decided not to include if: in the study.) Each individual has a card containing demographic Ghita (e.g., birth, birthplace, father's occupation, ethnicity, exiucation, training), and a card for each "career event" in this life. The career event cards contain information as to “nien the individual entered a particular status, Special training, responsibilities, location, and when he left the Sitatus. There are over 900 possible career event statuses; ‘the entire data deck contains just under 22,000 records. IFor purposes of this study, data from the career event cards ‘will be collapsed and punched on the demographic cards. Some Of the work of collapsing career events has already been done at the University of Pittsburg. Data on careers have been collapsed into eleven basic categories and the number of months each category is applicable to each individual has been summarized. The same has been done with data on Skills; frmm a series of roughly 100 Specialities, thirteen major 16 skills areas were constructed. Again, the number of months each skill area is applicable to each individual has been summarized. These subfiles will be employed in my analysis. All these data are derived from East European sanrces. In addition to current periodicals, Beck and his associates had access to Radio Free Europe (Munich), the Scuiost Institut (Munich), the Osteuropa Institut (Munich), the Osteuropa Institut (Vienna), the Sudetendentsche Archiv (Nthich), and public and private libraries throughout the Ihiited States. Data for the most recent Party Congresses wiJll come from several sources--Radio Free Europe publica- tixans, journals on Eastern Europe, and bibliographical Scnarces. This data will be catalogued using the same criteria as; the information above and placed on IBM cards. Independent Variables l. Age--upon joining party, at recruitment, in 1957, in 1966 2. Ethnicity-—dominant, Slovak, Jew, other minority 3. Education--primary, secondary, university; edu- cation area or training 4. Father's Occupation--agriculture, industry, white collar 5. Revolutionary Activity (inter-war and World War II)--participated, did not participate 6. Penultimate Office--party, government, mass, control, agitation, professional, other 17 The other independent variables, skills and career patterns, are derived by totaling the number of months in career statuses (career) or specialized areas of work (skills). The number of career statuses have been collapsed from 900 to eleven by Beck and from eleven to nine by the airthor. Skills have been collapsed from 100 plus to thirteen b3r Beck and from thirteen to nine by the author. An indi- vixiual is assigned a "career" and a "Skill" if more than 50 pexrcent of his career or skill focus is in a particular cate- gcxry; if the data do not reveal a clear pattern, an attempt ijIl be made to classify him on the basis of his life his- tcxry. When this is impossible he is classified as "not as- certainable . " 7. Career--government bureaucrat; party bureaucrat; mass;a professional culture;b professional tech- nical;c military; non-professional;d militant;e not ascertainable aThis category includes non-communist parties, mass 'Irganizations, student youth organizations, trade unions, and communications . bThis category includes culture, health and educa- tion, and non-technical management and professions. cThis category includes all non-political, technical Personnel--planning, managerial, economics, etc. dThis category includes skilled and unskilled labor, agriculture workers, artisans, clerks, etc. eThis category includes the "old revolutionaries," individuals who joined the party in the early 1900's and whose career pattern includes numerous career channels. 18 8. Skills--agriculture; industry;a administration; justice and law; control;b foreign relations; education and culture; manpower and labor; not ascertainable. Turnover in composition of the Central Committees and Politburos was over 50 percent in all cases. I have chosen to focus on the Central Committee and Politburo for several reasons. First of all, both bodies W“ are concerned with the functioning of the entire social sys— tem and, theoretically, will represent divergent interests. This is particularly true of the Central Committee. 'a E l—v Secondly, the Central Committee serves as an "elite pool" for the Politburo, Secretariat, and Council of Ministers. Third, we should expect that changes in the kinds of elites recruited into the Politburo or Secretariat will be preceded by changes in the Central Committee. Fourth, by focusing on the Central Committee we can isolate interests which are Constant-.132 represented (e.g., party bureaucrats, military) and those which become less crucial over time and decline in percentage representation (e.g., ethnic groups, mass parties). Finally, we can examine the way the "elite of the elite" (the Politburo) adapts to changes in functional reguisites for society; that is, does the elite group change its composition to meet changes in functional requisites or \ 11 - aThis category includes all technical skills—-plan- 111g, science, technology, commerce, economics, etc. a . bThis category includes communications, ideology, g1‘tation, and propaganda. 19 does it recruit individuals who can supply skills on a sub— elite level (e.g., the Central Committee) and then draw on these individuals in special problem areas? In a functional sense, the Politburo is the highest pol icy-making and decision-making body in a communist society. According to Stalin, "the Politburo is the highest organ, not of the state, but of the party and the party is the highest " directing force of the state."34 The Politburo represents a kind of fusion of the tOpmost pinnacles of the party and State. It serves as a forum for discussing and reconciling A 5.." interests of the party, state, and other institutions. Members of the Politburo usually have specific responsibili— ties in the party or the government.35 The actual decision— Ina1<1ng process in the Politburo is obscure, but the primacy of the Politburo as a decision—making body is well estab- liShed. From a functional standpoint the Central Committee is harder to define. Nominally, it is responsible for the e11tire work of the party, including selection of members of the Politburo and Secretariat. In practice it has little independent power, however. The only, and ‘very important, e3‘=<=eption to this seems to be when the Politburo is unable to resolve a Specific issue, as the Polish Politburo was in 1956, the Soviet Presidium in 1957, and the Czechoslovak 1Jolitburo in 1968. In crisis Situations like these the Cehtral Committee can exert a significant influence on the deVelopment of the polity. 20 The Central Committee performs other important func- tions as well. First of all, membership in the Central Com- mittee is a privilege and a reward-—in this sense it serves a legitimating function for elites. Second, it provides a means of access to key individuals and groups. Third, it serves as a source of information and knowledge for members of the Politburo and Secretariat. 5“ The membership of the Central Committee, according t0 Gordon Skilling, affords a good picture of the power elite at the upper and middle levels. Although the committee itself, as a collective body, ,5, does not in fact exercise the power ostensibly belong— ing to it under the party statute, it represents a gathering of the most powerful persons from various walks of life. . . . A high proportion of the Central Committee, perhaps about a half, may be regarded as the "hard core" who run the country, occupying the impor- tant party and government posts. Analysis of the Central Committee would be useful for any Scholar attempting to understand and predict change in a communist society. A basic assumption underlying this study, and indeed all elite studies which rely mostly on social background data, is that our understanding of elite behavior and our a“I’lllity to predict attitudinal change will be enhanced by a‘VVEIJ'eness of social characteristics. Unfortunately, in the case of Eastern Europe and the USSR, it is impossible to conduct attitudinal studies to determine the validity of this assumption. Donald Searing, in a recent study of elite soc=:i.alization in five Western countries, concluded that while 21 demographic and career variables were relevant for predicting attitudes some variables were more relevant than others.37 Also, when compared cross-nationally, different variables emerge as being particularly meaningful for each country. The process of elite socialization, aside from social char- acteristics, is of crucial importance in forming attitudes. While the states under consideration in this study possess ”be: similar political systems they are very diverse in terms of culture, history, tradition, level of industrialization, and many of the other variables which influence the socialization ‘1': "' LVWI‘I Process. We are going to be extremely limited as to the kinds of conclusions we can make concerning attitudinal change in the elite strata as a function of demographic/ career variables. Nevertheless, this kind of a study is a necessary forerunner of attitudinal studies and, in Spite of the limitations, will enable us to draw meaningful conclusions about recruitment patterns in communist industrializing SOCieties. 22 NOTES 1See, for example, Gabriel Almond and Sidney Verba, fie Civic Culture (1963); Robert Alford, Party and Society The Anglo-American Democracies (1963); Angus Campbell, et a1.,Tlections and the Political Order (1966); Ralf ahrendorf, Class and Class Conflict in Industrial Society (1959); S. M. Lipset, Political Man (1959); S. M. Lipset and Stein Rokkan, eds., Party Systems and Voter Alignments: 93055 National PerSpectiveS (1967). 2There are some notable exceptions to this observa- tion . See, for example, Franz Borkenau, European Communism (1953); Richard Burks, The Dynamics of Communism in Eastern EurOpe (1961), and Zbignew K. Brzezinski, The Soviet Bloc 1S) 1 . 3Some of the more recent studies of non-ruling Parties include Thomas Greene, "The Communist Parties of Italy and France: A Study in Comparative Communism," World M: XXI, 1 (1968), 1-39; Sidney Tarrow, peasant Com- EEEEEEEEyn in Southern Italy (1967); Tarrow, "Political Dualism and Italian Communism," American Political Science Review, :LJ(I:, l (1967). Richard Cornell has developed some useful tlyDO'theses which can be utilized in studying communist non- ruling parties, "Comparative Analysis of Communist Movements," wall of Politics, xxx, 1 (1968). J 4Merle Fainsod, Smolensk Under Soviet Rule (1958); ohn Armstrong, Soviet Bureaucratic Elite (1959); and Sidney A gloss, Conflict and Decision-Making in Soviet Russia: \as\eStudy of Agriculture policy 1953-63 (1965). 5Ghita Ionescu, Politics of European Communist W (1967) . 6Burks, op. cit.; see also Gordon Skilling, The Ws of Communist East Europe (1966); J. F. Brown, i\eNew Eastern Europe (1966); William E. Griffith, Communism ‘1 Euro e, I (1964) and II (1966); Alvin z. Rubenste_in, ed., ““‘--___Jl_ ‘§§E§EEflygnist Political Systems (1966); and Robert Scalapino, The Communist Revolution in Asia (1965). ‘ a 7Paul Shoup, "Comparing Communist Nations: PrOSpects {gr an Empirical Approach," American Political Science Review, 11, 1 (1968), 185-205. 8See Meyer in "Symposium of Comparative Politics," 8 \lavic Review, XXVI, 1 (1967), 1-29. all) 9See Robert S. Sharlet, "Systematic Political Science erg Communist Systems," in'Symposium," op. cit., for a useful 1-‘—5.que of the functional approach. ________. (x as nus-n A‘sttlilollucl 23 10H. Gordon Skilling, "Interest Groups and Communist Politics," World Politics, XVIII (1966), 435-451. 11H. Gordon Skilling, "Soviet and Communist Politics, A Comparative Approach," Journal of Politics, XXII (1960), 12Robert C. Tucker, "On the Comparative Study of Com— munism," World Politics, XIX, 2 (1967), 242-257. 13Cornell, op. cit. 14Roger W. Benjamin and John H. Kautsky, "Communism and Economic Development," American Political Science Review, LXII, l (1968), 110—124. See also John H. Kautsky, Communism and the Politics of Development (1968). 15See Frederick C. Barghoorn, Politics in the USSR (1966) for a structural-functional approach to communist Studies. Ploss, op. cit., is a useful example of a decision— making study as are Jeremy R. Azrael, ManageriaLPower and 9e“ .fikZZELSEE Politics (1966), and Joel L. Swartz and William Keech, AGrOUp Influence and the Policy Process in the Soviet Union," 75%:331153an political Sciepge Review, LXII, 3 (1968), 340—352. b. fleeud G. Meyer, in The Soviet Political System (1965), com— blues a systems analysis approach with bureaucratic model suilding. For a study of elite stratification see George K. Rghlleller, "The Politburo," in Lasswell and Lerner, World Exilfifagggtionary Elites (1965), and Carl Beck, Aggregative ocreer Characteristics of Eastern European Political Leaders, incaSiEnal Paper, University of Pittsburg (1968). See Meyer f0 Edinger, Political Leadership in Industrialized Societies, r a developmental approach to communist studies. 16Maurice Duverger, Political Parties (1954), p. xiii. th 17Frederic J. Fleron, Jr., "Soviet Area Studies and hie Social Sciences: Some Methodological Problems in Commu- 531: Studies," Soviet Studies, XIX, 3 (1968). 13Ibid., p. 321. 19Lasswell and Lerner, op. cit., p. 4. in 20See, for example, Daniel Lerner, "The Nazi Elite," GerLasswell and Lerner, op. cit.; Maxwell E. Knight, _Tll_e_ W Executive, 1890-1933 (1952); Lewis Edinger, "Continuity weStChange in the Background of German Decision—makers," _T_h_e_ 'Do ern Political Quarterly, XIV, 1 (1961), and Edinger, RepSt—Totalitarian Leadership: Elites in the German Federal 1Jblic," American Political Science Review, LIV, 1 (1960). 5.3. _. . »~_ll._ 3. 11:! A 24 21See, for example, T. B. Bottomore, Elites and Societ (1964); Suzanne Keller, Beyond the Ruling Class (1963 ; Dwaine Marvick, ed., Political Decision-Makers (1961); Lewis J. Edinger, Political Leadership in Industrial Socie- ties (1967); Carl Beck and James Malloy, Political Elites: ‘3 Mode of Analysis (1968). 22See, for example, Joseph Schlesinger, Ambition and blitics (1966); Lasswell and Lerner, op. cit.; Donald Matthews, United States Senators and Their World (1960); and Austin Ranney, Pathways to Parliament (1965). 23A few process oriented studies of East Europe are available although most of them are economic rather than Politically oriented. These include Andrezej Korbonski, Mos of Socialist Agriculture in Poland, 1945-1960 (1965); Paul Kecskemeti, The Unafpected Revolution (1961); George R. Feiwel, The Economics of a Socialist Enterprise (1965); Jan - Michal, Central Planning in Czechoslovakia (1962); John M. Montias, Central Planning in Poland (1962); and Frederick C. PI'Yer, The Communist Foreign Trade System (1963). P 24D. Tomasic, "Political Leadership in Contemporary Toland," Journal of Human Relations, IX (1961), 191-205; D. Xomasic, "The Rumanian Communist Leadership," Slavic Review, TE $1961), 477-494; R. Bass, "East European Communist Elites-- elr Character and History," Journal_of International Affairs, St (1966), 106-117; Zygmunt Bauman, "Economic Growth, SSCial ructure, Elite Formation: The Case of Poland," International mSciepce Journal, XVI (1964), 203-216; Grey Hodnett, Sghe Obkom First Secretaries," Slavic Review, XXIV (1965), P 6~653; Ionescu, op. cit.; Anonymous, LeadingfiPositions and erSonalities in Eastern Europe (1957); J. Rothschild, The fifirfiunist Party of Bulgaria (1959); Daniel Kubat, "patter'n‘s Of eadership in a Communist State--Czechoslovakia," Journal Wntral European Affairs, XXI (1961); D. and E. Rodnick, etes on Communist Personality Types in Czechoslovakia," We Opinion Quarterly (1950), 81-88; Richard F. Staar, he Central Committee of the United Polish Workers Party," ggurnal of Central Eurgean Affairs, XVI (1957), 371—383; aar, "The Central Apparatus of Poland's Communist Party," J Mal of Central European Affairs, XXII (1962), 337—348; 0hr! Armstrong, "Party Bifurcation and Elite Interests," 8 . Wt Studies, XVII (1966), 417-430; Beck and McKechnie, wcal E—lites: A Select Computerized Bibliography (1968). 1:1 . 25393: for example, Milton Lodge, "Soviet Elite Par- 1) clpatory Attitudes in the Post-Stalin period," American 1968), 827—81“; Gglitical Science Review, LXII (September, Orge Fischer, The Soviet System and Modern Society (1968); F ogederic J. Fleron, Jr., "The SovietTolitical Elite: ASpects Political and Economic Development in the USSR," Paper ) I 0—! K {‘7‘ 1' ’11 [8:1 25 presented at the 1968 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., September 2-7; Fleron, "Cooptation as a Mechanism of Adaptation to Change: The Soviet Political Leadership System," Polity, II, 2 (Winter, 1969); Michael P. Gehlen and Michael McBride, "The Soviet Central Committee: An Elite Analysis," American Political Science Review, LXII, 4 (December, 1968), 1232-1241; Beck, "Career Characteristics," op. cit.; Swartz, op. cit. 26Frederic J. Fleron, Jr., "Note of the Explication of the Concept 'Elite' in the Study of Soviet Politics," gnadian Slavic Studies, II, 1 (Spring, 1968), 111-115. 27Schlesinger, op. cit. 28The dates marking the end of the New Course, based r on official pronouncements, are different for each country. 53 They are January 13, 1957, in Bulgaria; June 13, 1957, in .4 Czechoslovakia; February 26, 1957, in Hungary; October 27, 1957, in Poland. t" 29The closing dates for the study are quite uniform fer the Politburos—-January l, 1969, for Bulgaria, Poland, and Hungary, April 17, 1969, for Czechoslovakia. Recent data fOr the Central Committees of Poland and Czechoslovakia were not available although I did manage to get a small sample from the 13th Party Congress, KSC, held in May, 1966. The closing date for Poland is January, 1966; for Bulgaria and Huhgary, the most recent party congresses-—November, 1966 and December, 1966, reSpectively. I? 30Fleron, "Soviet political Elite," op. cit., and ischer, 0p. cit. E 31Fleron, "Soviet Political Elite," op. cit., 6; ilsizabeth powell, "Dynamics of political Elife—REEFuitment—- Elle Cases of the Soviet Union, Bulgaria, and Czechoslovakia," npublished Master's Thesis, University of Georgia, 1969. 32Duverger, op. cit., 168. 2 33For propositions about elites see Keller, op. cit., 12-242; Lasswell, op. cit., 1-96; Bottomore, op. ci’—50‘t., -82. 34George K. Schueller, "The Politburo," in Lasswell, ~52324;_21§., 98. 35H. Gordon Skilling, The Governments of Communist \East Europe (1966), p. 88. 361bid., p. 99. 26 37Donald D. Searing, "The Comparative Study of Elite Socialization," Comparative Political Studies, I, 4 (January 1969), 471-501. ,3. Le CHAPTER I I POLITICAL DEVELOPMENT IN EASTERN EUROPE The study of political development and social change ls Central to political science. Analysis of the recruitment and circulation of elites is just one of several sub-fields o f this more general problem. Elites in communist societies, seaejking to control the developmental process, stress the I)1:‘:i~lnacy of the political system over the economic System. A basic assumption of this study is that political elites cannot c:()1'l1;rol socio-economic develOpment, as thoroughly as they Wteuld like, without modifying their skill characteristics. That is, industrializing societies present socio-economic h:"~"':)blems that political elites cannot cope with, unless they Q3~‘l:her acquire technical Skills or share decision-making I><>Vler with non-political elites who possess these skills. As l-‘lzanne Keller concludes from her study of "strategic" elites i 11 industrialized societies: "No single strategic elite can teday know all there is to be known, and none can perform all the functions involved in social leadership."1 The pur- ste of this chapter is to examine the developmental process 11') Eastern Europe, focusing on the interdependence of the 27 28 political system and the economic system in communist industrializing societies. "The study of society," according to G. M. Sorokin of the Institute of Economics of the World Socialist System, Moscow, "rightly leads one to believe that the main criterion 0f Social progress is the degree of development of productive f<'>1'<:e:s."2 Economic development is an essential prerequisite fOr achieving the goals of a communist society. Indeed, com- munist leaders are quite explicit in defining success in economic development as the ultimate criterion for determin- ing the most progressive social system. The underlying assumption of communist economics is that economic laws can be made to Operate in accordance with human will.3 Decisions regarding allocation of resources, rate of economic growth, DI‘iorities in investment, and satisfaction of consumer demands Qan and should be made by political leaders. The chaos of the market and the inequalities of capitalism can be elimina- ted in a centrally planned economy. Economic progress can be QQnsciously organized by society; human wants will be satis- tied. These assumptions, which are now under review by Q(r-onomists in Eastern Europe, were accepted by political leaders and applied in rebuilding the economic systems follow- ing World War II. Success in the economic Sphere was consid- QIl:~ed essential, both for ideological and for pragmatic reasons. However, the ideological link between elites and 1“asses was seriously weakened by events in the 1950's. F5”: “nu ; . 9'4" .EEDEE. .I .. .. 29 Demonstrations against the regime occurred in East Germany, Czerflnoslovakia, Poland, and Hungary—-dissatisfaction with the reconomic system was in part responsible in all cases. Ideology is an important aSpect of the theory of legitimacy of communist states: The meaning given in Marxist-Leninist political ter— lninology to the word "ideology" is now generally under- stood as the reasons or faiths which lead the members F‘* of a "conscious" group, class or society, to see how 5 q their "praxis," i.e., their own creative action becomes ' ‘ the cause of change in their own surroundings and cir- cumstances. Projected upon the background of legitimacy in a communist state ideology (or in this case using David Easton's precise expression: "The legitimating ideology") can be defined as the link of allegiance of the population to the expressed motives and values of F the regime. ‘1' ()‘3£3 of the expressed motives of the regimes in communist SGeieties, a motive which has been utilized to justify ‘GaClonomic sacrifice, is that of developing the economic con- tatitions for the transition to communism. Political elites I“aintain that society can develop and control the economic system and make it reSponsive to human needs. In search of this goal communist elites reserved 13or themselves the "interpreter of reality" function for the ‘Vvhole of society. They assumed responsibility for all (iecision-making; they also were held responsible for the Ilresults. With failures in the economic and social spheres (Dame challenges, from professionals and laymen, to the role (of the party in the social system. As the ideological link (declined pragmatic considerations increased in importance. Support for the party as the interpreter of reality became 30 increasingly dependent upon its ability to meet real, immediate, tangible demands, that is, support for the party became contingent upon its ability to cope with and manage a developing socio-economic system and upon its ability to make available the goods and services demanded by the masses. This is eSpecially applicable to Eastern Europe where eco- Fan. nomic prosperity and rationality appear to be more important iSSues than they are in the USSR. Eckstein and Bendix at- tribute this to two factors: greater willingness of Soviet citizens to accept power objectives and nationalism in lieu of economic success, and the late arrival of the Protestant work ethic as a cultural norm in the USSR.7 This is not to say that ideology is no longer an ilnportant variable influencing decision-making. The ideo— lOgical goals of political elites are essentially the same as before. What is changing, it seems, are some of the lIlnderlying assumptions of the decision-making process. That is, political elites are becoming increasingly aware (bf the limits of political, ideological criteria as guides ”to decision-making in certain non—political areas, e.g., the economic system. Approaches stressing rationality, fiefficiency, pragmatism, and decentralization of decision- lmaking are becoming increasingly important in Eastern Europe.8 An examination of economic development in Eastern IEurope will reveal some of the problems which are forcing elites to go beyond political considerations in economic 31 decixsion-making, and, presumably, which will be reflected in tune elite recruitment pattern in each of the countries. Economic Development in Eastern Europe Industrialization in communist societies can be cOnceived of as occurring in two different, although not mUtually exclusive, phases. The first phase, a period of eJ'Itensive growth, occurred in Czechoslovakia, East Germany, HuIilgary, and Poland in the 1950's. Transition to the second phlase, a period of intensive growth, is now occurring in these countries. Each phase is distinguished by the kinds, cl“lantity, and quality of inputs and outputs of the economic S31V13tem and, theoretically, by the methods of administration. Following World War II, political elites in Eastern IE:‘Jrope initiated a period of rapid industrialization which 11>:aralleled that of the Soviet Union. Economic development Zifollowed the Stalinist model, with emphasis on the develop- Inlent of heavy industry and concentration of decision-making II>ower in the central party apparatus. High rates of economic Eirowth were achieved through extensive inputs of capital and 3hnobilization of labor reserves. During the extensive stage (Bf economic deve10pment, the problems which accompanied the EStalinist planning system were mitigated by increasing (capital and labor inputs. High growth rates can be stimu- Ilated and maintained for a period of time, but, as Ota Sik (concludes, "as soon as the extensive development has passed Ea certain limit, or goes further under specific economic 32 economic conditions and brings insoluble internal economic cxnrtradictions, it is actually a Special kind of ineffec- tivea, economically negative development, the consequences Of an inadequate system of management which must be changed as Soon as possible if there is not to be a catastrophe."9 Economic growth rates in East Germany and Czechoslovakia in the early 1960's supported Sik's observation. Growth rates during the 1950's, as Table 1 indicates, Were fairly impressive, exceeding or equaling those of vVGBS‘S‘tern Europe. Growth of industrial production was much €51TGaater in Eastern than Western Europe from 1950 to 1960 and a-‘t><3ut the same from 1960 to 1964.10 Other industrial TABLE 1 GROWTH OF GNP, PREWAR TO 196411 (ANNUAL PERCENTAGE INCREASES) ‘\ 1951- 1956- 1961- 1951- “‘¥ 1955 1960 1964 1964 333u1garia 5.9 7.3 4.3 5.9 Qzechoslovokia 3 .6 6 .6 1.3 4.0 'JEast Germany 7.2 4.9 2.7 5.1 ilsungary 5.5 4.2 4.6 4.8 ilpoland 4.8 5.0 5.0 4.9 Rumania 8.6 3.5 4.9 5.7 Average East Europe 5 . 9 5 . 2 3 1 Average West Europe 5 . 3 4 . 7 5 . 2 5 . 33 measnxres--e.g., growth of heavy industry, fuels, energy, chenricals——a1so demonstrate the high growth rates in the industrial sectors of East Europe.12 The percentage in- crease in gross national product declined noticeably in EaStern Europe from 1961 to 1964, however, especially in the industrially advanced countries of East Germany and Czechoslovakia (see Table 1, page 32). The pattern of economic growth reflects the priori- ties of the Stalinist model, especially in terms of consump- tion and consumer welfare. (See Tables 2 and 3, page 34.) 1*Elggs in growth of consumption have influenced consumption levels. Table 3 is a comparison of per-capital consumption J~evels in West Germany and Austria, countries with the t-":l<)sest social and historical ties to East Europe, with con- SS11mption levels in East Germany, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland. Data in Tables 2 and 3 indicate two serious economic IDroblems which faced East European political leaders in the (Early 1960's. First of all, in spite of impressive growth Jrates in the industrial sphere, personal consumption remained Jrelatively low. Belassa, for example, concludes that the areal income per capita of the working population in Hungary \nas on the average about 10 percent lower in 1955 than in 1949.13 Second, and perhaps even more serious, growth rates in the 1960's began to decline--eSpecially in the economically advanced countries. The growth rates in Eastern Europe vary inversely with per capita GNP (in West Europe there is no 34 TABLE 2 GROWTH OF PERSONAL CONSUMPTION IN RELATION TO GNp14 (RATIOS OF GROWTH RATES, IN PERCENT) 1951- 1956- 1961- 1951- Country 1955 1960 1964 1964 Czechoslovakia 31 55 136 55 East Germany 16oa 90 22 114 Hungary 36 100 84 71 Poland 85 84 76 84 Austria 100 100 112 104 France 111 83 114 102 Denmark 75 76 102 85 West Germany 86 105 106 97 aThe high ratios recorded for East Germany from 1951 to 1960 result from mass migration to the West. TABLE 3 COMPARATIVE LEVEL OF PERS NAL CONSUMPTION PER CAPITAI Country prewara 1950 1955 1960 1964 West Germany 100 100 100 100 100 Austria 81 82 78 79 79 Czechoslovakia 95 100 71 63 57 East Germany 85 54 68 68 60 Hungary 87 69 52 49 48 'Ppland 45 60 48 42 40 a1936 for West Germany; 1937 for Poland and Czecho- Slovakia; 1938 for the other countries. 35 clear pattern). This is another indicator of problems facing centrally planned and administered economies as they develop. Reasons for the declining growth rates appear to be endemic in the management of the economic system. In the 1950's it was possible for political leaders to overcome the weaknesses accompanying centralized planning (lack of proper criteria for allocation of resources, the complexity Of centralized decision-making, the problem Of incentives, and the impediments to diffusion of technological innova- tions) by increasing inputs Of manpower and resources. In the 1960's, however, the inefficiencies Of the centralized model are more critical than they were during the formative period. The size and complexity Of the economic system cause decision-making to be more wasteful than ever. Large labor reserves are either exhausted or significantly reduced. Quality and variety in production are now more important than quantity. This is particularly true for countries which are attempting to compete on an international level with other technically advanced societies. Transition from the exten- sive to the intensive stage of economic development is pro— ceeding rapidly.16 Two prominent East European economists, the late CBcar Lange and Ota Sik, concur with this prognosis. Both Inen agree that a period of extensive development is necessary and both agree that it should be followed by radical changes in the system of management. Lange, in 1958, indicated that 36 the end of the transition period would be marked in part by substitution of methods of administration and management by 17 ' new methods based on economic laws. Sik, commenting on the developmental process, states: The decisive source for the growth of production is, on the one hand, the quantitative expansion Of inputs, i.e., the volume Of means Of production and number of produc- tive workers, and, on the other hand, the qualitative development of factors increasing the social productivity of labour, i.e., the technical improvement of means of jproduction, increase in knowledge, abilities and experi- ence Of_productive workers and leading personnel (by in- creasing their qualificationS), the development of sci- entific knowledge and its application to technOlogy, and progressive growth of social combination of labour (co- operation and division of labour).18 (Italics added) According to Sik, societies in Eastern Europe are entering the latter period--the period of intensive development. The measures he uses in Czechoslovakia to substantiate this con- clusion include productivity of labor, development of indus- trial production, age Of machines and equipment, trends in investment cost, and annual increments in productivity of labor and in the number of workers in industry.19 The Old system of management should be changed com- pletely in the period of intensive development. Sik, as Lange did much earlier, advocates the establishment of a socialist market, decentralization Of decision-making, more involvement Of economic Specialists in the economic system (instead of in state planning agencies), and a complete revamping Of the state bureaucracy. Economic decision-making should conform to economic laws; the role Of central planning agencies should be Specifically delineated. (Under the new 37 system central planning agencies remain in charge of dis- tributing the bulk Of investment resources for the economy in accordance with long range investment plans; they will directly control large investments of countrywide importance; and they will have adequate power to intervene directly into production activities of enterprises and industries.)20 Economists in Eastern Europe are very much concerned with the problems of economic efficiency and, evidently, quite serious in their attempts to introduce rationality into the economic system.21 According to some economists, rationality demands at least some extension Of the workings of the free market. This would, of course, threaten the very existence of the state's economic bureaucracy.22 Opposition to reform programs is both ideological (the relationship of politics to economics) and practical (the entrenched position of a state bureaucracy). However, the necessity for reform seems inescapable. Ota Sik indicates that elites in Czecho— slovakia have attempted to alleviate some of the pressures on the economic system by recruiting more specialists into economic management positions.23 This, he says, will only serve as a stop-gap measure. (One Of the problems initially facing political elites in the USSR and Eastern Europe was that Of recruiting reliable, skilled personnel into manage- ment positions. This problem stimulated concentration Of technicians into the central party bureaucracy. However, the percentage of trained individuals has increased to the .point where it is possible to decentralize decision—making 38 and, as Sik indicates was occurring in Czechoslovakia, to increase the Skill attributes Of management personnel on all administrative levels.) In spite of Opposition from "dogmatists," economic reform has been initiated in Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Hun— gary, and Poland. Reforms in Czechoslovakia and Hungary are more extensive than those in Bulgaria and Poland, although the outcome Of the Czech reform program is now in doubt. Poland and Bulgaria are experimenting with piecemeal reforms similar to those initiated in the USSR. Reform will have to occur in two areas to be meaning- ful: first of all, changes in the system of economic admin- istration and planning will have to occur and, secondly, technical rationality will have to increase as a norm govern- ing recruitment Of decision-makers. It is imperative, economists agree, for economic systems in the stage of in- tensive economic development to operate under a system which maximizes rationality in decision-making and efficiency in resource allocation. The implications of these criteria for the polity are important and opposition to reform is exten- sive, eSpecially in Bulgaria and Poland. We cannot predict, on the basis of this study, the outcome of the struggle; however, we can determine if the changes which appear neces— sary in the composition of elite bodies are occurring. That reform Of some kind is needed seems to be beyond diSpute; whether recruitment to elite positions reflects this need is an empirical problem. (Unfortunately I can only partly 39 answer the question on the basis of this study Since I have no way to test the relationships among career variables, attitudes, and behavior.) Economic Development and Political Change Almond and Powell, in a developmental approach to comparative politics, outline three dimensions on which sys— tems can be compared to determine the level Of develOpment: role differentiation, secularization, and sub-system autonomy.24 A more developed system is distinguished from a less developed system by higher levels Of role differen- tiation and secularization ("secularization is the process whereby men become increasingly rational, analytical, and empirical in their political action"), and by high sub-system autonomy.25 In capability terms, those systems with high sub-system autonomy have relatively versatile and continuous capability; secularized systems utilize rational decision- making criteria. However, Almond and Powell indicate that "the dominant and legitimate culture of totalitarian systems is ideological in its intellectual characteristics. There are limits on rational calculation and analysis."26 The implications Of Almond and Powell's framework for communist states are Obvious: they will be "less deve1- Oped" SO long as they remain monocratic and ideological. There is general agreement among scholars on the decline Of ideology in "mature" communist societies. Ionescu, for 40 example, states that "revolutionary fervour is gradually replaced by reSpect for efficiency and good administration . . ideology is gradually being replaced by pragmatism."27 The transition is not a smooth one, however, for there is considerable evidence pointing to a generational conflict between the Old revolutionaries and the young rational administrators.28 Technical rationality, it is claimed, will become the norm in economic decision-making. If this occurs there will be considerable spill-over into the polit- ical system, eSpecially in societies stressing political control of economic development. Barrington Moore and Herbert Marcuse both predicted technical rationality as a possible trend influencing leader— ship selection as the USSR industrializes.29 Recent studies Of elite recruitment in the USSR substantiate these predic- tions.30 In mature communist societies the party will be forced to change its role from that of a system builder to that of a system manager. If it accepts this role it will have to recruit into the party apparatus individuals who possess the technical competence to manage the economic system. A developed, intensive economic system poses dif- ferent management problems from an economic system in the extensive growth stage. Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland are now in the intensive stage of economic development, although there are differences among them in levels Of development. Bulgaria remains more "suited" for the classi— cal communist system Of planning and management. Political 41 elites have followed the Soviet lead, however, and are experimenting with reform measures.31 The time period Of this study, 1957-1968, is partic- ularly well suited for analysis for several reasons. First of all, the countries under consideration were beginning to feel the dislocations in their economic systems discussed above. Second, the political atmOSphere in Eastern Europe was relatively stable. Third, polycentrism in the communist world provided political leacers in Eastern Europe a little bargaining room with the USSR. Finally, the Soviet Union was having economic problems and was beginning to experiment with economic reforms. In Short, there was both a rationale for reform and a favorable political atmOSphere in which to effectuate it. Elites in Eastern EurOpe have essentially two alter— native responses tO the dislocations of economic development and both Of these have Significant implications for the political system. On the one hand, political elites could continue to dominate economic decision-making and refuse to implement meaningful economic reform. If they choose this course it seems inevitable that economic development will be curtailed. Consequently the legitimacy of the party, which, to a large extent, is based on its commitment to economic development, would decline. The gulf between non-political elites and political elites, or between those stressing rationality in decision—making and those stressing ideology, would widen. Political leaders would become more dependent 42 upon the Soviet Union for economic assistance and political support and it seems inevitable that all this would lead to declines in social freedoms and to more repressive regimes. The other course,that of effectuating changes in recruitment and decision-making criteria, poses somewhat different problems for political leaders. Milton Lodge con- cludes from his study of elite participatory attitudes in the Soviet Union that Soviet political elites are being forced to rely increasingly on specialists in decision-making Situa- tions. "Over the years all the elites, the Party included, increasingly came to rely on scientific knowledge and expert Skills as crucial resources in the decision-making process."32 He also noted that Specialist elites increasingly described themselves as participants in the policy-making process, with economic elites indicating the greatest increase in perceived influence from 1957 to 1965, and making the greatest push for more influence in decision-making. Specialists increasingly feel they Should be making policy.33 It seems reasonable to assume that political elites in Eastern Europe are faced with Similar challenges. The party claim to authority in communist societies is linked to its claim to ideological supremacy.34 However, Marxist ideology Offers some Objective standards against which the aSpirationS and the accomplishments Of political elites can be measured. Ideological considerations are becoming less important in Eastern Europe-—the party's role as the 43 "interpreter of reality" is becoming increasingly dependent upon its ability to meet tangible goals. It seems likely that non-political elites, stressing rationality in decision- making, are challenging the authority Of the party in certain policy-making areas. The imposition Of rationality as a norm governing recruitment and decision-making would carry with it a potential reduction Of power over the economic system. It would also increase the possibility that elites in other non—political areas would seek more autonomy. In short, alterations in the recruitment and decision-making process could mean a reduction in power for political elites. Recent events in Czechoslovakia underscore another danger accompanying reform. Reform measures, it seems, must be limited to the economic system and must conform to Soviet expectations. The initiation of reform in one area, however, will almost certainly stimulate pressure for reforms in other areas. This does not necessarily mean that the introduction Of rationality as a norm in recruitment and economic reform would lead to a pluralist political system. Research by Gehlen and McBride indicate that elites with Specialized skills have been present in the Central Committee Of the CPSU since 1952.35 Although there is evidence of conflicts in the decision-making process, there are few indicators Of a trend toward a pluralist political system. Other factors, such as the role perceptions Of Specialized elites, linkages among and within elite groups, social traditions, and the 44 ideological commitment of Specialized elites are also crucial in assessing the potential for a pluralist political system. It does seem evident that the political/cultural context in Eastern Europe would be more conducive to pluralism than that of the Soviet Union.36 The approach Of this study is developmental--that is, it is assumed that the societies under consideration are developing societies (from an economic standpoint the point is beyond dispute), that they are characterized by secular- izing value systems and increasing role differentiation. Whether they will develop sub-system autonomy, a necessary characteristic Of democratic pluralism, as the society modem»- izes, cannot yet be determined. Democratic pluralism is a possible, although not a necessary, outcome of modernization. The question of pluralism is beyond the scope of this study. A major effort will be directed towards examin- ing the hypotheses outlined in the first chapter. An attempt also will be made to utilize Fleron's typology in analyzing the data, not only to increase our understanding Of changes in the recruitment process but also to test the relevance Of the typology to Eastern Europe. The challenges of political and economic development, as the discussion above indicated, are intertwined in Eastern Europe. Political legitimacy depends ultimately on the ability of the parties to meet the technical requirements of an industrializing society and the social aSpirations Of the masses. This is incumbent upon them because of their 45 insistence on maintaining control of the entire social system. It seems the transition from an extensive to an intensive economic system will either force political elites to alter decision-making criteria and recruitment patterns to adjust to changes in the functional requisites, or force them to become even more reliant on the Soviet Union for economic and political support. Both alternatives have positive and negative consequences for the political leaders. Summary Political elites in Eastern Europe are confronted with system building problemS--the central problem, according to Meyer, is that of establishing and/or maintaining author- ity.37 The party claim to authority is being challenged by differing conceptions Of rationality as defined by the pro— fessional elites. The masses are restive; indications are that they are escalating their demands for political and social liberties and material benefits. Crucial problem areas include economic reform, establishment of rationality in decision-making, a lessening Of police power, elimination Of arbitrariness in the legal systems, development of loyal, qualified cadres, reconciliation with ethnic groups, recon- ciliation with professionals, and attention tO consumer demands. There are also indications Of antagonisms within the party bureaucracies. "Ideologically" oriented party members have differing perceptions of reality from those "pragmatically" 46 inclined. A substantial number of party bureaucrats are in danger Of losing their positions if skill requirements are established. It is generally not necessary for government bureaucrats to possess technical skills-—the British Civil Service functions quite well in a "generalistic" tradition. If political elites in Eastern Europe wish to maintain dominance over the entire social system, and maximize their independence from the USSR, they will be forced to alter recruitment and decision-making criteria so as to include Specialists in crucial decision-making areas. In so doing they will risk losing some of their decision-making power to "rational" elites, however (and, it seems, run the risk of "socialist intervention"). The alternate course Of action--to refuse to adjust to changes in the economic sys- tem—-will lead to failures in the economic sphere, dissatis- faction among the masses, alienation from the professionals, and increased reliance on the USSR. Analysis of the data, which follows in Chapters III and IV, will proceed on two levels. First of all, I will be seeking to determine if recruitment trends reflect the changes in the economic systems discussed above. Specifi— cally, are there trends supporting the assumption that economic development will force political elites to alter recruitment criteria. If so, we should expect to see more individuals recruited with rational—technical Skills, careers, and education areas, and fewer elites recruited with non— rational skills, careers, and education areas. 47 Second, variables will also be analyzed which, hope- fully, will reveal characteristics Of each party in a broader sense. That is, a discussion of changes as measured by demo— graphic, career, and age criteria not only will improve our understanding of some of the forces influencing party recruitment trends in each country, but also will increase our ability to comprehend current policies and to make pre— dictions regarding the future. This discussion will indicate something of the "nature" of each party as revealed by the attributes Of its leaders. 48 NOTES 1Suzanne Keller, Beyond the Ruling Class (New York: Random House, 1963), p. 70. 2G. M. Sorokin, "Basic Trends Of Economic Develop- ment in the Socialist Countries Of Europe," in M. C. Kaser (ed.), Economic Development for Eastern Europe (New York: Macmillan, 1968), p. 3. 3OSkar Lange, Problems of Political Economy Of Socialism (Warsaw, 1958). 4Paul Kecskemeti, The Unexpected Revolution (Palo Alto: Stanford University Press, 1961), pp. 1264239. 5Ghita Ionescu, The Politics Of the European Commu- nist States (New York: Praeger, 1967), p. 24. 61bid., p. 25. 7Reinhard Bendix and Alexander Eckstein, "The Cul- tural and Political Setting Of Economic Rationality in Western and Eastern Europe," in Gregory Grossman (ed.), Value and Plan: Economic Calculation and Organization in Eastern Europe (Berkeley: University Of California Press, 196677—557‘245-254 and 263-265. 8See Grossman, Op. cit.; Gregory Grossman, "Economic Reforms: A Balance Sheet," Problems of Communism, XV, 6 (November-December, 1966); and Michael Gamarnikow, Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe (Detroit: Wayne State University Press, 1968). 9Ota Sik, Plan and Market Under Socialism (White Plains, N.Y.: International—Arts and—sciences Press, 1967), p. 50. 10Maurice Ernst, "Postwar Economic Growth in Eastern Europe," in New Directions in the Soviet Econom , Part IV (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1966), p. 883. 111bid., p. 880. 12Alfred Zauberman, Industrial Progress in Poland, Czechoslovakia, and East Germany, 1937-1962 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1964), pp. 119-165. 13Bela Belassa, The Hungarian Experience in Economic Planning (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1959), p. 236; 49 see £1180 Nicolas Spulber, The State and Economic Development in lkistern Europp (New York: Random House, 1966), pp. 48-52. 14Ernst, op. cit., p. 886. 15Ibid., p. 887. 16Alexander Erlich, "Economic Reforms in Communist Courrtries," Dissent (May—June, 1967), p. 313. 17Lange, op. cit. 18Sik, Op. cit., p. 48; see also Belassa, Op. cit.; JOth M. Montias, Central Planning in Poland (New Haven: Yale UniJIersity Press, 1962); Jan M. Michae1,7Central Planning in Qgechoslovakia (Palo Alto: Stanford University Press, 1960); zuxl Stanislaw Wellisz, The Economies Of the Socialist Bloc (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1964). 19Sik, Op. cit., pp. 47-99. 20Er1ich, op. cit., p. 317. 219. J. D. Wiles, "Rationality, the Market, Decen- tralization and the Territorial Principle," in Grossman, Value and Plan, op. cit., p. 184. 22Ibid. 23Sik, Op. cit., pp. 83, 84. 24Gabriel A. Almond and G. Bingham Powell, Jr., _C.9mparative Politics: A Develppmental Approach (Boston: LJ-t‘lzle, Brown, 1966). 25Ibid., p. 24. 26Ihid., p. 312. 27Ionescu, op. cit., p. 26. 28See Gamarnikow, Op. cit., Chapter 6; Alfred G. Meyer, "Authority in Communist Political Systems," in Lewis Edinger (ed.), Political Leadership in Industrialized Socie- ties (New York:——Wiley,‘l967), p. 106. 29Barrington Moore, Jr., Terror and Progress USSR (New York: Harper and Row, 1954); Herbert Marcuse, Soviet Marxism (New York: Columbia University Press, 1958), p. 1§9. 30See, for example, George Fischer, The Soviet System gpd Modern Society (Chicago: Atherton Press, 1968); Frederic 50 C. Fleron, "Toward a Reconceptualization of Political Change in the Soviet Union," Comparative Politics, 1, 2 (January 1969); Boris Meissner, "Totalitarian Rule and Social Change," Problems of Communism, XV, 6 (1966), 56-61; Meyer, Op. cit. 31J. F. Brown, "Reforms in Bulgaria," Problems Of Communism, XV, 3 (May-June, 1966), 18. 32Milton Lodge, "Soviet Elite Participatory Attitudes in the Post—Stalin Period," in American Political Science Review, LXII (September 1968), 839. 33Ibid., pp. 827-834. 34Ibid., p. 834. 35Michael B. Gehlen and Michael McBride, "The Soviet Central Committee: An Elite Analysis," in American Political figience Review, LXII, 4 (December 1968), 1232-1241. 363endix and Eckstein, in Grossman (ed.), Value and 21523. op. cit., p. 245. 37Alfred G. Meyer, "Authority in Communist Political Systems," in Lewis Edinger (ed.), Political Leadership in Industrialized Societies (New York: John Wiley, 1967), p. Tfiii, CHAPTER III THE CENTRAL COMMITTEE Elite recruitment trends, generally Speaking, support the predictions outlined in the first two chapters. However, Significant differences are revealed among the countries, reflecting levels Of economic development, vary- ing historical and social traditions, party origins, and elite-mass relationships. Background Variables Social origins Of Central Committee members changed very little from 1957 to 1966. Table 4, page 52, compares members on the basis of father's occupation, population of place of birth at time of birth, and predominate economic characteristics Of birthplace. The percentage Of those coming from proletarian backgrounds has increased only moderately in Czechoslovakia and Hungary with both countries recording a larger percentage increase in individuals with agricultural backgrounds. Increases in both countries have come at the expense of those with white collar backgrounds; in Czechoslovakia this group has been virtually eliminated in the Central Committee. A sizeable increase in white collar representation is recorded in Bulgaria, however, this 51 52 TABLE 4 SOCIAL BACKGROUND CHARACTERISTICS OF CENTRAL COMMITTEE MEMBERS (IN PERCENT) BOPa KSC HSWP puwp 1957 1966 1957 1965 1957 1966 1957 1965 Father's Occupation n= 30 26 35 46 15 37 43 41 Agriculture 53 54 23 28 40 46 25 24 Industry 20 8 66 69 27 29 44 51 White Collar 26 39 12 2 34 24 30 25 Total 99 101 101 99 101 99 99 100 Population of Birthplace at Time of Birth n- 53 56 44 58 22 23 45 54 100,000 plus 2 5 22 22 46 17 58 58 10,000-99,999 19 15 18 14 28 30 12 12 Under 9,999 79 80 61 64 28 52 29 30 Total 100 100 101 100 102 99 99 100 Economic Char- acteristics of Birthplace n- 48 41 44 62 22 23 52 54 Industrial 37 24 65 64 63 21 77 76 Agricultural 62 76 36 36 37 78 23 23 Total 99 100 101 100 100 99 100 99 N- 62 137 83 109 63 101 79 86 aIn this and in subsequent tables the following abbreviations are used: BCP: Bulgarian Communist Party; KSC: Communist Party Of Czechoslovakia; HSWP: Hungarian Socialist Workers Party; PUWP: Polish United Workers Party. 53 time at the expense of the working class. The increase is understandable-—Bulgaria has problems recruiting qualified, trained personnel--but the decline of members with working class origins is surprising. If we compare representation Of each sector with percentage contribution to GNP, Poland exhibits by far the best balance, 31 percent, 41 percent, and 28 percent, reSpectively in 1960.1 The industrial sectors in Hungary and Poland contribute almost identical percentages to total GNP. Agriculture in Poland contributes a larger percentage to GNP than in Hungary, 31 percent and 24 percent reSpec- tively, yet the percentage Of individuals from agrarian backgrounds in Hungary increased significantly from 1957 to 1966 while remaining stable in Poland. The data on popula- tion and economic characteristics Of place Of birth under- score this fact. The only country recording any significant change in birth population is Hungary. In terms Of economic characteristics little change was recorded in Czechoslovakia and Poland but Bulgaria and Hungary made Significant negative changes (negative in terms of what we might expect from Marxist parties). In the case of Hungary two possible eXplanations for this un-Marxian behavior come to mind. First Of all, the party apparatus in the larger cities, eSpecially Budapest, was largely destroyed in the 1956 revolution and its after- math. Party "liberals" who sided with Nagy were purged following the revolution. Kadar was forced to go outside 54 the cities, which party dogmatists controlled, in order to get support and to rebuild the party apparatus. Secondly, in 1958 party leaders in Hungary started a drive to collec- .tivize agriculture, in spite of bitter Opposition from the peasants. Agriculture remains a problem area in Hungary and attention to agricultural affairs is to be expected. Data on skills, which will be discussed below, Sup- port the first explanation. Only 10 percent of the Central Committee members possessed Skills in agriculture in 1966, but 78 percent of the members come from predominately agri- cultural areas. Kadar, it appears, has built his base Of support on individuals from medium to small sized cities whereas the party under Rakosi derived most of its personnel from medium to large sized cities. (Zhivkov, in Bulgaria, gained control of the apparatus at about the same time Kadar did in Hungary and, like Kadar, faced serious opposition from factions within the BCP. Changes in Bulgaria and Hungary measured by economic characteristics Of place Of birth are Significant and the problems faced by Kadar and Zhivkov in building a base Of support undoubtedly influenced these changes. Similar changes occurred in the CPSU under Khrushchev.) Ethnicity With the exception Of Poland, as Table 5, page 55, indicates, minority group representation has tended to be very stable in East Europe. Purges in the early 1950's 55 TABLE 5 REPRESENTATION 0F MINORITY GROUPS IN CENTRAL COMMITTEESa (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1966 1957 1965 1957 1966 1957 1965 Dominant 96 94 77 77 92 93 77 85 Slovak 00 00 19 20 00 00 00 00 Jew 2 3 00 1 6 6 19 12 Other 1 3 3 2 l l 4 3 Total 99 100 99 100 99 100 100 100 aBulgaria: 91% Bulgar; Czechoslovakia: 66% Czech, 28% Slovak; Hungary: 93% Maygar; Poland: 99% Pole. removed most Of the prominent Jews from leading party posi- tions in Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Rumania. Ironically, Poland, which is the most ethnically pure, has the second highest percentage Of minority group representation. Jews, who make up only .1 percent of the population, represented 19 percent of all Central Committee members in 1957 and 12 percent in 1965. (After the 1968 PUWP Congress, however, elites of Jewish origin had been almost completely eliminated from the Central Committee.) Numerous explanations have been Offered for the recruitment of minority group members into elite bodies. Two Of these, association with revolutionary activity and expertise, will be examined here. 56 Table 6, which compares majority and minority groups for all countries on the relevance of revolutionary activity, supports the thesis that minority groups tended to become diSprOportionately involved in revolutionary movements.2 (Revolutionary activity includes inter—war communist move- ments and guerrilla activity in World War 11.) TABLE 6 PARTICIPATION IN REVOLUTIONARY ACTIVITY FOR ETHNIC GROUPS IN EASTERN EUROPE Minority Majority 1957 1966 1957 1966 Did Participate 65 47 51 39 Did Not Participate 35 53 49 61 Total 100 100 100 100 N - 43 45 261 329 Czechs were Slightly more "revolutionary" than their Slovak counterparts. Jews, in all countries, were conSpic- uouS for their involvement in revolutionary activity. In Poland, 72 percent of all Jews who were members of the Cen— tral Committee from 1957 to 1965 participated in revolution- ary movements. Jews and Slovaks in Poland and Czechoslovakia are better educated than their Polish and Czech counterparts. In Poland, 50 percent of the Jews in 1957 had university training as did 80 percent of the Jews in 1965 (Poles, 46 57 percent and 57 percent). The figures for Czechoslovakia are summarized in Table 7. TABLE 7 FORMAL EDUCATION OF ETHNIC GROUPS IN THE CENTRAL COMMITTEE, KSC (IN PERCENT) 9532p Slovak .Qppgp 1957 1966 1957 1966 1957 1966 n = 65 85 16 22 2 3 Primary 55 50 45 32 50 00 Intermediate 9 ll 00 9 50 00 University 13 20 25 28 ? 00 66 Not Ascertainable 23 20 31 32 00 33 Total 100 101 101 101 100 99 The possibility that revolutionary activity and high education were mutually exclusive--that is, that minority members were selected either for their revolutionary creden- tials or their expertise, was also investigated. There is no support for this assumption; in fact there is a tendency for high education and revolutionary activity to correlate. Career Characteristics Education level Of Central Committee members has risen in the last decade but not dramatically. Poland and Czechoslovakia have made the largest gains, but Czechoslovakia 58 is still lowest in terms Of higher education. (Jeri Hendrych, following the 1966 Party Congress in Czechoslovakia, reported that 50 percent Of the new Central Committee members and candidates had university training.3 The data I have on the 1966 Central Committee is minimal and would not reflect this.) TABLE 8 EDUCATION LEVEL OF CENTRAL COMMITTEE MEMBERS (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1966 1957 1965 1957 1966 1957 1965 Primary 18 3 53 44 3 4 9 4 Secondary 29 11 8 10 6 7 2 6 University 27 30 14 25 31 35 46 57 Not Ascertainable 25 56 24 22 60 55 42 33 Total 99 100 99 101 100 101 99 100 The increases in the "university" category for Hun— gary and Poland reflect a large number of recruits from polytechnical schools. In percentage terms the number of Central Committee members with post-graduate work declined in Hungary and remained stable in Poland. In Chapter II it was predicted that a crucial variable influencing the ability Of communist parties to adapt to industrialization would be the acquiring Of tech- nical skills by the party elite. The education level might 59 not be as important, in the final analysis, as the areas Of specialization and competence of the elites. Analysis was made in two areas to determine if there is a trend toward COOptation Of individuals with technical Skills. First Of all, elites were classified according to education area or training and, secondly, they were classified according to the skills acquired in the course of their careers. The following tables summarize these results. TABLE 9 EDUCATION AREA OR TRAINING (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1966 1957 1965 1957 1966 1957 1965 n = 46 62 65 88 52 9O 59 69 Technical 11 32 17 29 17 20 32 37 Worker/Artisan 22 9 61 44 60 51 33 20 Education/Health 13 24 5 8 6 13 13 11 Control 15 ll 5 5 4 6 5 7 Law 20 18 6 8 12 9 12 14 Agitation 20 6 6 6 2 1 5 10 Total 101 100 100 100 101 100 100 99 N : 62 137 83 109 63 101 79 86 These findings support the assumptions previously made regarding technical training. Substantial increases were recorded in Bulgaria and Czechoslovakia. The relatively 60 low figures for Hungary and Czechoslovakia reflect differ- ences in education systems. Most of the individuals in the "worker" category in these countries are skilled workers or artisans who have received specialized training. The data also indicate that the parties in Czechoslovakia and Hungary are more active and/or successful in recruiting workers into the party apparatus than Bulgaria or Poland. Trade union leaders and workers generally favor economic reform measures. Union leaders in the recent crisis in Czechoslovakia were very active in their support for Dubcek. Hungarian union leaders, who are well represented in the Central Committee (see Table 10, page 61), are young, and generally Of worker origin whereas their counterparts in Bulgaria and Poland tend to be white collar professionals. If we make the assumption that elites with technical skills and labor leaders would be more likely to support reform measures and a rational economic system than, say, administrators and control personnel, then the recent, rela- tively bold reforms initiated in Hungary and Czechoslovakia are more understandable (see Table 10, page 61). In these countries the "rationalizing" elites account for about 50 percent Of the Central Committee members in 1966. (Data for the 1966 Czechoslovak Central Committee would, I suSpect, reinforce this conclusion.) It can be argued that the Cen- tral Committee possesses little real power tO initiate reform SO this conclusion is meaningless. Technically Speaking, the Central Committee does not initiate reform but members Of the 61 TABLE 10 SKILL CHARACTERISTICS OF CENTRAL COMMITTEE MEMBERS (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1966 1957 1965 1957 1966 1957 1965 n - 62 136 83 109 63 100 59 65 Technical 15 25 37 45 38 39 23 28 Administrative 40 38 27 24 23 22 27 3O Manpower 5 2 4 3 l3 l5 4 3 Control 30 16 26 18 10 12 30 21 Education/Culture 3 9 5 8 6 6 9 12 Other 6 9 1 3 11 5 8 6 Total 99 99 100 101 101 99 101 100 Central Committee, most Of whom occupy rather important party and state positions, implement the reforms. Also, it was the Central Committee in Czechoslovakia which made the final decision to oust Novotny and support Dubcek. Aside from the power relationship, the fact that high party and state personnel have Spent most Of their careers in tech- nically oriented positions enhances the possibility Of suc- cessful reform. Figures 1 and 2, pages 62 and 63, respectively, indicate that the changes Observed in terms of skill char- acteristics constitute definite trends in Bulgaria and Czechoslovakia. Hungary and Poland fluctuate widely but show small overall gains in percentage of elites with 62 60' Bulgaria ______ Czechoslovakia ,”\. ...... Hungary [1” ‘\\ — ooooo POland 1” \\ 50J 40‘ .p 5 o 30‘ H o m 20' 10‘ 01 1957 1958-59 1960-62 1963—66 1966 Members Recruits Recruits Recruits Members Figure 1. Recruits and Members Possessing Technical Skills Percent 63 Bulgaria ------ Czechoslovakia ...... Hungary - ----- Poland 30- 204 lOi 0" 1957 1958-59 1960-62 1963-66 1966 Members Recruits Recruits Recruits Members Figure 2. Recruits and Members Possessing Control Skills 64 technical Skills. Most noticeable is the increase in coop- taizion Of technical elites in the 1960 to 1962 period in aJJL countries. In Hungary this increase came at the expense Oii elites with control Skills. The decline Of technical elites in the 1963 tO 1966 period in Hungary and Poland could reflect several things--a "backlash" by party general— ists, fear Of tOO much innovation by elites, a less than wholehearted commitment to reform, or the assumption that technical expertise was sufficiently represented on the Cen- tral Committee. The decline in Hungary came after the reforms were initiated (1966); in Poland it came before the reforms were initiated (1964). Perhaps Gomulka was forced to assure party regulars that reform would not result in a Significant change in recruitment criteria in order to get the necessary support. Recruitment of technical personnel increased in Bulgaria from 1963 to 1966. Bulgaria still remains lowest in percentage of elites with technical skills in the Central Committee; indications are that party dogmatists are less than enthusiastic about the recruitment of elites with tech— nical qualifications. Events in 1967 and 1968 in Czechoslovakia revealed that a rather Significant transformation had occurred in the Czechoslovak Party. Recruitment of elites with technical skills was not curtailed in 1966 as it was in Poland and Hungary. Although it would be presumptuous to assume that this is what finally caused Novotny to lose control Of the 65 party, it undoubtedly was a factor. There seems to have been more sentiment and support for continued cooptation of elites with technical expertise among middle level party elites in Czechoslovakia than in Poland and Bulgaria. Czechoslovakia had more serious economic problems than other East European countries. Party elites in Czechoslovakia would not be as threatened, on the whole, by emphasis on technical expertise as elites in Bulgaria and Poland since a larger percentage Of them already possessed these skills. It will be interesting to see if events in Czechoslovakia will affect recruitment in other East European countries. The focus Of the Polish Party Congress, which came after the intervention, was on ideological purity. Cooptation to the Politburo reflected this but data are not available on the Central Committee. Career Patterns Data on career patterns have been analyzed to deter- mine changes in career types, which career types possess which Skills and education areas, ages Of different career types, penultimate Office (which will give some indication Of interpenetration Of party and government), revolutionary activity and career patterns for minority groups. Party Bureaucrat, predictably enough, emerges as the dominant career channel for all countries. Increases came primarily at the expense Of militant and non-profes- sional categories.4 The predicted increase in the number Of 66 Professionals coopted into the Central Committee was supported only by Bulgaria. The other countries coopted more cultural professionals but the number Of technical, :nonrparty career types decreased in Czechoslovakia and Poland while remaining constant in Hungary (see Table 11). TABLE 11 CAREER PATTERNS FOR CENTRAL COMMITTEE MEMBERS (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1966 1957 1965 1957 1966 1957 1965 Government Bureaucrat 5 13 13 15 13 14 13 16 Party Bureaucrat 23 37 24 29 13 33 28 31 Mass 21 7 17 13 21 20 14 14 Professional (Culture) 10 16 5 10 13 13 6 11 Professional (Technical) 0 10 l6 14 11 ll 10 8 Military 11 9 4 4 2 3 10 8 Non-professional 2 l 4 6 22 2 1 l Militant 27 7 12 6 3 3 14 9 Not Ascertain- able 2 l 6 4 3 0 4 1 Total 101 101 101 101 101 99 100 99 The data indicate a bureaucratization and Special- ization Of career Channels in Eastern Europe. In this respect, differences among the countries have been reduced. 67 A closer examination Of party bureaucrat, government bureau- Craia and mass channels based on Skills and education area reveals some rather striking differences, however. First of all, in terms Of education area, party bureaucrats and mass leaders in Hungary and Czechoslovakia maintain their worker bias. Over 60 percent Of the party bureaucrats received a workplace education as opposed to 27 percent and 13 percent in Poland and Bulgaria reSpectively (see Table 12). TABLE 12 EDUCATION AREA OF PARTY BUREAUCRATS (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1966 1957 1965 1957 1966 1957 1965 n = 10 16 14 25 6 26 14 22 Technical 10 25 7 20 0 8 14 27 Worker 30 13 64 64 100 65 64 27 Health/Education 0 25. 0 0 O 15 l4 14 Control 20 6 O 0 0 0 0 0 Law 20 31 7 4 0 12 0 9 Agitation 20 0 21 12 0 0 7 23 Total 100 100 99 100 100 100 99 100 N = 13 51 20 32 8 33 22 27 In terms of skill characteristics party bureaucrats in all countries in 1966 were primarily administrators (59 68 Percent to 73 percent). Poland had the second lowest Percentage with technical skills and the highest with control Skills. Bulgaria was lowest in technical skills (8 percent) followed by Poland (14 percent), Hungary (15 percent),and Czechoslovakia (22 percent). Government bureaucrats in Hungary and Czechoslovakia followed the general pattern as party bureaUcratS although they were better educated. The percentage of government bureaucrats in Poland with technical educations was very high (85 percent) compared with Hungary (47 percent) and Czechoslovakia (50 percent). In terms Of technical Skill characteristics, however, the countries are very Similar. Over half Of the mass leaders in Hungary were labor leaders (next high, Poland with 25 percent) with workplace educations. In the other countries they were generally leaders of cultural or political organizations with control or administrative backgrounds. Many mass leaders in Bul- garia and Poland are lawyers or professional people. A breakdown of elites according to penultimate Office allows us to isolate other important characteristics. We should expect, first Of all, that industrializing countries with limited skilled manpower resources would concentrate most Of these resources in central party and government positions. Second, we should eXpect declines in interpene- tration of party and government personnel as career channels become established. Finally, declines in ideologues recruited 69 into the Central Committee and an increase in professionals are to be expected. Table 13 summarizes changes in penultimate Office over time. The percentage recruited directly from profes- sional status increases in all the countries except Poland. It is interesting to note, in this regard, that Czechoslo- vakia and Hungary, which have initiated meaningful reforms, are more willing tO coopt professionals than Bulgaria and Poland—-even though the former countries already have a much higher percentage of individuals with technical skills on their Central Committees than the latter. (Data on the Politburos, which is presented in the next chapter, makes this fact more understandable. The Hungarian Politburo is quite low in terms Of elites with technical skills and pro- fessionals. Not SO with Czechoslovakia, however, The Czechs are committed to reform and, evidently, not hesitant about Sharing power with professionals.) The data support the first expectation but with some country Specific reservations. In terms Of education level, central party Officials tended to be more highly educated than regional leaders. In Bulgaria this was not the case, however; almost twice as many regional party leaders had high education as central party Officials. High government Officials, with the exception of Czechoslovakia, were better educated than party Officials on any level. In Czechoslo- vakia very few government officials had university training but most possessed technical Skills. 70 TABLE 13 PENULTIMATE OFFICE FOR CENTRAL COMMITTEE MEMBERS (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1966 1957 1965 1957 1966 1957 1965 n = 59 136 72 105 53 98 75 85 Regional/Local Party 17 26 28 39 19 23 19 30 Other Party 15 12 11 10 6 10 12 11 High Government 27 31 17 14 31 28 33 34 Regional/Local Government 3 6 10 10 4 4 l 1 Mass 15 9 7 5 21 12 15 13 Control 8 7 l 1 2 2 8 6 Agitation 0 2 7 6 2 4 4 1 Professional 2 5 10 12 9 13 4 1 Other 12 3 10 4 7 3 5 4 Total 99 101 101 101 101 99 101 101 N = 62 137 83 109 63 101 79 86 A higher percentage Of regional and local party leaders in Czechoslovakia and Hungary possessed technical skills than in Poland and Bulgaria (32 percent, 22 percent, 17 percent, and 13 percent respectively). Over 40 percent of the central party leaders in Hungary possessed technical skills, a larger percentage than in any other country. High government Officials in Hungary were lowest in this category, however. All the countries coopted professionals into the 71 Central Committee in 1966; Hungary, once again, was highest in the percentage coopted with technical skills (77 percent). None of the coopted professionals in Poland possessed tech- nical Skills. Interpenetration, as measured by the number Of party bureaucrats holding government positions and the number Of government bureaucrats holding party positions at the time of cooptation, has increased in three countries while hold- ing stable in the fourth. Hungary and Czechoslovakia were Significantly higher in this regard than Bulgaria and Poland. In Poland, career lines appear to be very well developed. The difference undoubtedly stems in part from a higher avail- ability Of trained personnel in Poland. In summary, the percentage of Central Committee mem- bers in Poland and Bulgaria with formal technical training exceeds the percentage in Czechoslovakia and Hungary. In Czechoslovakia and Hungary, however, the percentage with technical Skills exceeds that of Poland and Bulgaria. Party personnel in Czechoslovakia and Hungary are more actively involved in the economic system. This conclusion is sup— ported by the data On interpenetration. Career lines appear to be more institutionalized in Poland and Bulgaria; indi- viduals with technical training become administrators upon entering the party. These Observations are supported by Carl Beck who, in a similar study, also concluded that the technician category was more relevant for elites in the Cen- tral Committees of Hungary and Czechoslovakia than Poland 72 and Bulgaria.5 The party bureaucratic category was also less relevant, he concluded, for Hungary and Czechoslovakia. Party leaders in Czechoslovakia and Hungary are more worker oriented, have less Specialized training in such areas as law and agitation, and are less ideologically inclined than those in Bulgaria and Poland.6 Data on age and relevance of revolutionary activity will help explain these differences. Age Differences Observed among Central Committees in career characteristics are reinforced by data comparing age at cooptation and age in 1957 and in 1966. Duverger's hypothesis is substantiated, at least by communist parties in Eastern Europe. The mean age of Central Committee mem- bers remained relatively stable from 1957 to 1966 (see Table 14). (In the Soviet Union, however, mean age Of Central Committee members increased from 51 to 56 in the same time period.)7 TABLE 14 MEAN AGE OF CENTRAL COMMITTEE MEMBERS BCP KSCa HSWP PUWP 1957b 54 (SD-10) 52 (SD-10) 49 (SD-ll) 49 (SD-6) 1966 53 (SD- 8) 47 (N/A) 48 (SD-10) 53 (SD=9) a1966 statistics bMean age Of United States senators, by comparison, was 55 in 1950. 73 The only increase in mean age was registered in Poland; mean age in the other countries declined. Jerry Hough, in his analysis Of party elites in the USSR, predicted continued economic problems unless Older bureaucrats were removed.9 Mean age for Central Committee members in 1966 in Bulgaria and Poland is just Slightly lower than Central Committee members in the CPSU. The implications are undoubtedly the same. Data on age at cooptation is given in Table 15. Age in cooptation in Bulgaria is about five years higher than in the other countries; this is compensated for, in the case Of Poland, by a length of service which is about five years longer. TABLE 15 MEAN AGE AT COOPTATION BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957a 46 (SD=ll) 45 (SD-9) 43 (SD-10) 42 (SD=6) 1966 48 (SD- 7) 43 (SD-8) 44 (SD-10) 43 (SD-8) . aMean.agE,at cooptation for United States senators in 1950 was 50. Changes have occurred in the age distribution Of party elites, particularly in Czechoslovakia and Hungary. The mode for all countries except Bulgaria was 50 years in 1957; in 1966 it was 40 for Hungary and Czechoslovakia (see Figures 3 and 4, pages 74 and 75). In 1966, 67 percent of the Central Committee members in Hungary and 60 percent Of Percent 74 Bulgaria ------ Czechoslovakia 70 ' H . ...... ungar; -._.-. Poland A 60) A K i K .I. \ I \ 50 J I .\ z 1 .I \ .I \ 401 304 20. 10: 30 4O 50 60 70+ years Figure 3. Mean Ages Of Central Committee Members. 1957 75 701 Bulgaria ------ Czechoslovakia 60‘ ...... Hungary - ----- Poland 504 °' 40‘ 4..) a o o h o ‘lBOM 20. 10‘ 0V ’ years Figure 4. Mean Ages of Central Committee Members, 1966 76 the members in Czechoslovakia were under 50. In Bulgaria and Poland the figures are 44 percent and 39 percent respec- tively. Sixty percent Of the delegates to the Hungarian Party Congress in 1959 were under 40.11 Kadar has rejuve- nated the HSWP with an infusion Of young blood; it seems likely that the same thing might have happened in Czecho- slovakia. The dynamism Of the parties in these countries will be affected by the ability Of party elites to provide advancement Opportunities for younger party members. A generation gap between higher and middle level party elites appears to have developed in communist countries. Those parties which can successfully bridge this gap, with a min- imum Of infighting, will be in the best position to bring about reform. The HSWP appears to be most successful in this regard. An important variable influencing the prOSpects for economic reform and a more rational social system, is the age distribution associated with particular Skill and career characteristics. The Optimal distribution, it seems, would be a combination Of young party bureaucrats, who are more prone to support reform, and Older professional elites. This is the Situation existing in Hungary. The mean age of party bureaucrats and administrators is 43, that Of professional technicians is 57, and those with technical Skills 51. Individuals with control skills are 6 to 13 years younger than their counterparts in other countries (see Table 16, page 77). 77 TABLE 16 DEVIATIONS FROM THE MEAN--CAREER AND SKILL CATEGORIES, 1966a BCP KSC HSWP PUWP Mean Age 53 53 48 53 Career Government Bureaucrat 0 2 5 1 Party Bureaucrat - 4 - 4 - 5 — 5 Mass 7 4 - 2 - 1 Professional (Culture) 2 - 2 0 2 Professional (Technical) - 5 — 4 9 5 Military — 2 - 2 - 8 1 Skills Technical -11 - 3 3 0 Administrative - 2 - 3 - 5 — 1 Labor - 3 10 0 - 3 Control 1 6 - 2 0 Culture 3 0 0 - 1 aCareer or skill mean minus the mean for all members. b1965 figures. In Bulgaria, the Opposite Situation Obtains with party bureaucrats (M-49) and administrators (M=51), who are Older than the professional technocrats (M-48) and elites with technical skills (M=42). Control of the party apparatus thus remains in the hands of Older, non-technical elites. The pattern in Poland is similar to that in Hungary, with party bureaucrats ten years younger, on the average, than professional personnel and five years younger than elites with technical skills. Elites with administrative skills are about the same age as those with technical skills. 78 Table 16, page 77, summarizes deviations from the mean (in years) for career and skill categories. Revolutionary Activity Over half of the party elites in Bulgaria and Poland in 1966 participated in revolutionary or guerrilla activity before or during World War 11 (see Table 17). This fact is important for two reasons. First Of all, associations made in the course of these activities seem to have carried over into the political Sphere. Both Bulgaria and Poland have hfiluential partisan organizations; in the case Of Poland, the Partisans, who are allied with several veterans organ- izations, are presenting very real challenges to Gomulka's leadership. They are seeking to increase Poland's autonomy viS-a-vis the USSR and they also appear to be supporting economic reform--for nationalistic purposes. Gomulka is forced to rely on orthodox party members for support and TABLE 17 PARTICIPATION IN REVOLUTIONARY ACTIVITY (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1956 1966 1957 1965 1957 1965 1957 1965 Did Not Participate 16 47 52 56 66 77 28 43 Participated 83 53 48 44 33 22 72 57 Total 99 100 100 100 99 99 100 100 79 this lessens his own maneuvering room. Secondly, "revolutionary" types are less likely to be interested in rationalizing the economic system. This is, Of course, an Observation which cannot be supported empirically but there is a good deal Of support for it among students Of communism. In Czechoslovakia and Poland, revolutionary types are concentrated in government, mass and military career patterns. Almost half of the party bureaucrats in Bulgaria had revolutionary experience, along with 89 percent Of the mass leaders and 85 percent Of the military leaders. Most Of the revolutionary types in Hungary occupy government posi- tions (47 percent of the government bureaucrats had revolu- tionary experience) but only 10 percent Of the mass and none Of the military career types fit this category. Revolution- ary activity seems to be a very minor factor in Hungary, and in Poland and Czechoslovakia the category applies primarily to mass, control, and government personnel. Only in Bulgaria have party leaders failed to move the revolutionaries into government positions. In Poland, however, there is still a sizeable percentage Of party bureaucrats with revolutionary experience (41 percent) as compared with 19 percent in Hungary. Career Paths for Minority Groups Two countries, Czechoslovakia and Poland, had Size- able minority representation in their Central Committees. 80 In each instance, minority group career patterns varied from the majority. In 1957, 25 percent of the Slovaks in the Central Committee exhibited professional technical career patterns and only 5 percent Of the Czechs. This fact indicates dif— ferences in party composition and economic development between Slovakia and the Czech lands. The party in Slovakia, relative to its counterpart in Bohemia, was small and elitist. Slovaks also dominated the military and militant career paths. In 1965, however, this pattern had changed, with Slovaks relying diSproportionately on the party apparatus for ad— vancement (45 percent as Opposed to 25 percent for Czechs). Jews, in Poland, concentrated either in the party apparatus or the professions. This was true both in 1957 and 1965. Also, most of the diplomats in the Central Com— mittee were Jews. Reports on the 1968 Party Congress indi- cate that Jews have been virtually eliminated from the PUWP Central Committee. (Data on subsequent education-—party, military, foreign party, etc.-—which I planned to include, were not sufficient to draw any meaningful conclusions. The data do indicate that Hungary is lowest Of the countries in terms of subsequent party or military education; Poland is the highest.) 81 Summary The discussion above indicates the difficulty in making broad generalizations about political change in Eastern Europe. It seems that there are country Specific reservations for Virtually every conclusion made. Neverthe- less, change has occurred--it is possible to isolate trends and make some Observations regarding the nature and composi- tion Of each of the Central Committees. Table 18, page 82, reveals the direction Of change in each of the countries. The figures are derived by sub- tracting the percentage Of individuals in each category who were members Of the 1957 Central Committee and who have been dropped, from the percentage Of individuals in each category who have been added to the Central Committee Since 1957. Direction and magnitude Of change can be ascertained from the table but not the relative strength Of each category represented in the Central Committee. Generally Speaking, the predictions made in the first two chapters have been substantiated. The percentage of individuals with technical Skills and technical education or training increased Significantly in Bulgaria and Czecho- slovakia (see Table 19, page 84). Hungary, which had a high percentage Of individuals in these categories, changed very little. Poland registered small gains but remained low relative to the other countries. 82 TABLE 18 CHANGES IN COMPOSITION—— CENTRAL COMMITTEEa BCP KSC HSWP PUWP Education Area Agriculture and Mining 2 - 3 - l 0 Technical 23 23 - l 12 Skilled Worker/Artisan -ll —13 - 2 -22 Agriculture Worker/ Farmholder - 4 -12 — 2 - 5 Education/Culture l4 0 7 - 9 Health/Social Services 8 5 l 3 Control — 7 - 1 5 3 Law - l 2 - 5 6 Agitation -23 0 0 11 Skills Agriculture - l - 8 l 5 Industry 12 17 0 6 Administration 0 - 2 — 3 6 Justice - 2 l - 4 - l mea -3 -9 3 0 Control —15 - 8 3 -22 Foreign Affairs 0 l - 4 - 1 Education and Culture 8 10 3 7 Career Government Bureaucrat 10 3 - 1 10 Party Bureaucrat 18 5 15 1 Mass —19 — 4 2 4 Professional (Culture) 7 10 0 7 Professional (Technical) 7 - 4 3 - 7 Military - 4 - 3 2 - 6 Non-professional l 3 -23 0 Militant ~21 - 8 l —10 aPercent added in each category since 1957 minus percent dropped who were members 1957. The data support the hypothesis that "rational" skills (technical, health, education) would increase in importance while non—rational skills would decrease (control, ideology). Control skills increased slightly in Hungary but 83 representation in the Central Committee remained very low. Poland, while registering a substantial decrease in control skills increased the percentage Of elites with "non-rational" education areas (agitation, control). Most Of these are regional or local party Officials. The prediction that the data would reveal an increase in recruitment of professional personnel is only partially substantiated. Bulgaria made the largest percentage increase, 13 percent to 26 percent. Czechoslovakia and Poland in- creased slightly and Hungary, which had a relatively high percentage in 1957, did not change. Each country exhibits a rather distinct developmental pattern. Many factors influence the manner in which polit- ical elites perceive and solve problemS--these factors include, historical origins of the party, ideological orientations of elites, party members and masses, the rela- tionship between the party and the masses, and the level and rate of economic development. Table 19, page 84, listing contingency coefficients for major variables, gives some indication Of the relative strength Of the variables used in this study to determine changes in elite composition. These variables, unfortunately, measure only one kind of change. Intensive analysis of internal party affairs and attitudinal surveys are needed to analyze other major factors influencing party Operations. Perhaps the most striking conclusion we can draw from the data is the stability Of recruitment trends in the 84 TABLE 19 CONTINGENCY COEFFICIENTS FOR SELECTED VARIABLES BCP KSC HSWP PUWP Father's Occupation .1500 .2076a .1034 .2078a Birthplace: Population .0000 .1090 .1630 .0316 Birthplace: .Economic a a Characteristics .2567 .0744 .2634 .1081 Formal Education .3258a .1516a .1833a .0538 Education Area .2798a .18023. .0469 .0842 Skillsb .1264a .2046a .1004 .0173 2 aCorresponding x value significant at the .05 level. bTechnical skills only. parties. Skill and resource requirements have influenced cooptation but the elites recruited into the Central Com- mittee Of each party retain a high degree of internal con- sistency. This is particularly true in the case of Hungary (see Table 18, page 82); a significant transformation occurred in terms of background characteristics but career and Skill characteristics remained quite stable. The only exception to this was the emergence Of the party bureau- cratic career type. In percentage terms, rational skill groups were well represented in the Central Committees of Hungary and Czechoslovakia in 1957. Party bureaucrats increased in Hungary but they tend to be young and, evident— ly, pragmatic.12 Hungary and Czechoslovakia retain their 85 worker bias; party leaders in Bulgaria and Poland are Older, with revolutionary experience, better educated, with a higher percentage having professional backgrounds and edu— cations. In short, assuming that younger elites with tech— nical skills, industrial workers, and party Officials who have been involved in the economic System are more likely to support reform than party bureaucratic types, the disposition for reform and willingness to accept it has been much higher in Czechoslovakia and Hungary since 1957 than in Poland and Bulgaria. The percentage of elites with technical skills was higher in the former two countries in 1957 than in the latter two in 1966. Conflicts between technocrats and party apparats were not as likely to occur in Hungary and Czecho- slovakia. Finally, in Chapter II it was noted that East European economies were making the transition from extensive to intensive economic growth. Economists generally agree on the necessity of employing rationality as a guide to decision- making in an intensive economic system. Recruitment trends in Hungary and Czechoslovakia indicate that decision-makers in these societies have anticipated these changes in decision-making criteria. For example, it became clear in the Czech reform program that decision-making criteria had altered from 1957 to 1966 and that non-political elites were sharing decision—making power with political elites. The reform program in Hungary anticipates that a similar approach will be taken there. Recruitment trends in Poland and 86 Bulgaria indicate that political elites in these countries are aware of the problems posed by economic development but are reluctant to Share decision-making power. Bulgaria, which is still relatively underdeveloped, has not yet experienced the kinds Of economic problems discussed here. There is, however, general agreement among economists on the precarious condition Of the Polish economy. Political decision—makers in Poland are still unwilling to risk the uncertainties accompanying reform. 87 NOTES 1Maurice Ernst, "Postwar Economic Growth in Eastern Europe," in New Directions in the Soviet Economy, Part IV (Washington, D.C.: U{ST Government Printing Office, 1966), p. 878. 2R. V. Burks, The Dynamics of Communism in Eastern Europe (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1961). 3Radio Free Europe, "New Czechoslovak Central Com- mittee," June 14, 1966, p. 4. 4See Chapter 1, page 17, for an explanation of Career types. 5Carl Beck, Aggregative Career Characteristics Of Eastern European Political Leaders, Occasional Paper, Uni- versity of Pittsburg (1968), pp. 41, 42. 6Radio Free Europe, "New Czechoslovak . . . ," loc. cit. 7Alexander Dallin and Thomas Larson, Soviet Politics Since Khrushchev (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 19687} p. 29. 8Donald Matthews, U.S. Senators and Their World (Durham, N.C.: University of North Carolina Press, 1960), p. 14. 9Jerry Hough, "The Soviet EIite--In Whose Hands the Future," Problems Of Communism, XVI, 2 (1967), 20. 10Matthews, Op. cit., p. 14. 11William E. Griffith, ed., Communism in Europe, I (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1964), 215. 12Francois Feth, "Hungarian Communism," in William E. Griffith, ed., Communism in Europe, I (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1964), 219. CHAPTER IV THE POL ITBURO It is extremely difficult to draw conclusions regarding the functioning of the Politburo or the priorities and tactics of Politburo members from the kinds Of data employed in this study. The Politburo, unlike the Central Committee, is a small decision-making body--the personalities Of one or two individuals can completely dominate. Many factors besides those we are considering affect an individ— ual's personality. Dubcek and Novotny, for example, are very Similar in terms Of background characteristics but their perceptions Of reality are Obviously quite different. It is also much harder to classify Politburo members in terms Of skill and career attributeS-—many are general- ists, most have long and diversified party backgrounds. The "professional bureaucratic politician" is just beginning to emerge in Eastern Europe. The Party elites under considera- tion in this Study are a wide assortment Of revolutionaries, mass leaders, agitators, young technocrats, and Old party functionaries. In spite of these drawbacks, analysis of Politburo members in terms of background, career and Skill character- istics will increase our understanding Of the recruitment 88 89 process. First Of all, we will be able to evaluate the "fit" between the Central Committees and the Politburos. Second, we will be able to determine whether the structure of Opportunities differs for Politburo and Central Commit- tee members. Third, comparison among the countries will help explain different approaches tO problem solving. Fourth, we will be able to determine if the Politburos are being affected by the changes in skill requirements evidenced in the Central Committees. Finally, we will increase our understanding Of the information source Of the Politburo—- that is, the level at which individuals with non-political expertise are sharing in the decision-making process. Anal- ysis Of the Central Committee has revealed an increasing number Of individuals with non-political, rational Skill attributes Sharing power at this level. One purpose of this chapter is to determine if they are also Sharing power at the "elite pinnacle" and, if so, in which countries. Background Characteristics It was noted in Chapter III that the expectation Of an increase in the percentage Of elites coming from prole- tarian backgrounds and larger industrial cities seems justi- fied according to Marxist philosophy. The data, summarized in Table 20, page 90, indicate that while this expectation is supported in some countries it does not seem to be a very important consideration in others. 90 TABLE 20 SOCIAL BACKGROUND CHARACTERISTICS OF POLITBURO MEMBERS AND CANDIDATES (IN PERCENT) ' BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1968 1957 1969 1957 1968 1957 1968 Father's Occupation n = 8 7 7 4 6 12 9 11 Agriculture 63 43 14 50 66 50 ll 27 Industry 0 14 57 50 0 25 22 54 White Collar 38 43 28 0 33 25 67 18 Total 101 100 99 100 99 100 100 99 Population of Birthplace at Time of Birth n = 9 12 9 7 6 9 9 16 100,000 plus 0 8 11 14 34 22 44 44 10,000-99,999 11 16 22 14 17 ll 44 25 Under 9,999 89 76 66 72 50 66 11 31 Total 100 100 99 100 101 99 99 100 Economic Char- acteristics of Birthplace n = 7 ll 9 8 6 9 9 15 Industrial 14 27 77 38 50 33 78 73 Agricultural 86 73 22 63 50 67 22 27 Total 100 100 99 101 100 100 100 100 N I 11 17 9 13 12 15 9 16 Trends in Hungary and Poland, as measured by father's occupation, do support this assumption. Both Politburos declined in percentage of individuals from white collar backgrounds and increased in percentage from working class 91 families. Party elites in Bulgaria, however, increased their white collar bias. This, in part, is a reflection of the recruitment process of the Bulgarian Communist Party in the inter-war years. Lacking a labor movement Of any Sig— nificance, Bulgarian communists focused their attention on middle class intellectuals. The Communist Parties in Poland and Hungary had Similar recruitment problems but, unlike Bulgaria, they have altered their recruitment processes to include greater representation Of proletarians. Bulgaria does not possess the skilled manpower base of Hungary and Poland. Party elites in Bulgaria exhibit many Of the char- acteristics Of communist elites in less developed societies. Data on the other two background variables, popula- tion and economic characteristics Of birthplace, do not con- form tO what we might expect from Marxist parties. Changes in Czechoslovakia reflect a very Significant alteration in the power relationship between the Czech and Slovak Parties. In 1957, only one Politburo member was from Slovakia; Slovaks now have a majority on the Politburo. The Communist Party in Slovakia has "modernized" in terms Of skill and career patterns, but it still Operates in an underdeveloped society. The Hungarian Politburo mirrors changes in the recruitment process initiated by Kadar following the revolution. These were discussed in the previous chapter. 92 Ethnicity The last Jew was removed from the Polish Politburo in the 1968 Party Congress (see Table 21). This marks the first time since 1947 that there has not been a Jew on that Politburo. Bulgaria also was ethnically pure in 1968. It appears that nationalistic tendencies have taken their toll of the inter-war, ethnic minority communist leaders.1 TABLE 21 ETHNIC COMPOSITION OF EAST EUROPEAN POLITBUROS p93 KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1968 1957 1969 1957 1968 1957 1968 Majority 10 17 7 6 10 13 8 l6 Slovak 0 0 l 7 0 0 0 0 Jew 0 0 1 0 2 2 1 0 Other 1 0 0 0 0 ' 0 0 0 Total 11 17 9 13 12 15 9 16 The most Significant change has occurred in Czecho- slovakia where Slovaks now have a majority (as opposed to 11 percent in 1957). This transformation resulted, in part, from circumstances surrounding the attempted liberalization and Soviet intervention in 1968. Slovaks, who have been more interested in autonomy than liberalization, were not as adamant in opposition to the intervention as were the Czechs. It seems likely that the ratio will be altered but 93 the Situation is so unsettled that prediction is impossible. Revolutionary activity was relevant for all minority members in 1957 (as Opposed to 74 percent for majority mem— bers). ‘In 1968, however, minority members were lower than majority members in this attribute (33 percent-64 percent). In 1957, none of the minority personnel had a high education whereas in 1968 they tended to have higher education levels than majority members. Revolutionary activity, it appears, was probably an important factor in 1957 but of little Sig- nificance in 1968. Career Characteristics The education level Of Politburo members increased slightly in the last decade (see Table 22, page 94). There is very little difference between education levels Of Polit— buro and Central Committee members (see Table 8, page 58). Hungary is an exception to this, with a larger percentage Of Central Committee members having high educations than Polit- buro members. This is in keeping with Kadar's policy Of sharing decision-making power in certain areas with non- political Specialists, both in and out Of the party. What is even more interesting is the change in kind Of education in the high or university category (see Table 23, page 94). In all the countries except Hungary there is a noticeable shift toward COOpting elites with polytechnical educations as Opposed to those with university educations. 94 TABLE 22 EDUCATION LEVEL OF POLITBURO MEMBERS AND CANDIDATES (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1968 1957 1969 1957 1968 1957 1968 Primary or Less 36 12 56 38 58 40 33 18 Secondary 36 36 22 15 17 27 0 12 University 27 29 22 37 25 27 56 56 Not Ascertain- able 0 24 O 9 O 7 ll 14 Total 99 101 100 99 100 101 100 100 TABLE 23 EDUCATION AREA FOR POLITBURO MEMBERS WITH HIGH EDUCATIONS (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1968 1957 1969 1957 1968 1957 1968 n = 3 5 2 5 3 4 5 9 Polytechnical 0 40 0 40 0 0 0 44 University 100 60 100 60 100 100 100 55 Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 99 N = 11 17 9 13 12 15 9 16 Data on education area for all Politburo members and on skills developed during their careers reinforce this conclusion. Hungary, once again, is a conSpicuous exception to what appears tO be a discernible trend, that is, a significant increase in technical Skill attributes for 95 Politburo members in Eastern Europe (see Tables 24 and 25). TABLE 24 EDUCATION AREA FOR POLITBURO MEMBERS AND CANDIDATES (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1968 1957 1969 1957 1968 1257 1268 n - 10 11 9 13 10 13 8 14 Technical 10 27 ll 39 10 16 25 50 Worker 30 18 67 15 50 45 37 14 Health/Education 0 18 0 0 20 15 13 0 Control 20 9 0 8 20 8 l3 7 Law 20 18 22 31 0 15 13 14 Agitation 20 9 0 8 0 0 0 14 Total 100 99 100 101 100 99 101 99 N = 11 17 9 13 12 15 9 16 TABLE 25 SKILL CHARACTERISTICS OF POLITBURO MEMBERS AND CANDIDATES (IN PERCENT) p92 KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1968 1957 1969 1957 1968 1957 1968 Technical 11 24 0 53 18 26 0 32 Administrative 56 41 55 15 28 20 44 38 Manpower 0 6 ll 4 8 27 20 11 6 Control 33 18 22 15 18 20 44 19 Education/Culture 0 6 0 0 9 l3 0 0 Other 0 6 11 8 0 0 0 6 Total 100 101 99 99 100 99 99 101 96 The Hungarian Politburo is quite Similar to the Central Committee in terms of education area but not in terms Of skills. Control skills, which are very low in the Central Committee, account for over 25 percent Of the Skill attributes in the Politburo. Technical Skills are lower in the Politburo than the Central Committee, especially when the category is subdivided into industrial and agricultural skills. Only 13 percent Of the Politburo members in 1968 have technical-industrial skills as opposed to 29 percent Of the Central Committee members. However, most Of the Politburo members with control skills are ideologists who have been supplying the theoretical justification for the reform program (Komocsin, Szimrai, Ilku). The point is that technical expertise is not nearly as well represented on the Politburo as on the Central Committee. This is not true of the other countries. In Bul- garia and Poland technical skills are represented in about the same proportion in the Politburo and Central Committee. Technical skills in the Czechoslovak Politburo are more prominent than in the Central Committee (53 percent to 45 percent, reSpectively). (The "Czechoslovak Politburo" I am referring to is the one headed by Husak which was installed in April 1969. The Dubcek Politburo is very Similar, as measured by my variables, to the Husak Politburo.) What is particularly interesting is the radical change which has occurred in the Czechoslovak and Polish 97 Politburos. Technical skills, which were not represented at all in 1957, are well represented in 1968. It is also interesting to note that administrative skills are highest in Bulgaria and Poland-—just as in the Central Committee. Career Patterns Party Bureaucrats dominate the Eastern European Politburos in 1968 (see Table 26, page 98). Most of the changes that have occurred result from a decline in the "militant" category. In all countries the percentage Of professionals represented on the Politburo is below that Of the Central Committee, although the difference in the case of Bulgaria is very Small. The percentage Of profes- sionals has increased in all countries, however. The data indicate that the Hungarian Politburo probably relies more on Specialists outside the Politburo than any other coun- try; the other Politburos seem better equipped tO function without relying on sub-elites for expertise. Politburo members, with the exception Of those in Hungary, are gain— ing the requisite non-political skills to manage an indus- trializing society. A sharing Of decision-making power with other elites is most likely in Hungary. (Aggregate data will not allow us to make definite conclusions. The role of Ota Sik in Czechoslovakia, for example, is completely obscured in this kind Of gross analysis.) TABLE 26 98 CAREER CHARACTERISTICS OF POLITBURO MEMBERS AND CANDIDATES (IN PERCENT) BCP Ksé HSWP PUWP 1957 1968 1957 1969 1957 1968 1957 1968 Government Bureaucrat 0 0 33 23 8 13 0 13 Party Bureaucrat 44 41 33 38 25 33 0 31 Mass 0 18 11 8 33 27 33 13 Professional (Culture) 0 12 0 8 8 13 0 6 Professional (Technical) 0 12 0 8 0 O 0 6 Military 11 6 0 8 0 7 ll 13 Non-professional 0 0 0 0 8 0 0 0 Militant 44 12 22 8 l7 7 56 19 Total 99 101 99 101 99 100 100 101 Age Politburo members in Eastern Europe are young--in most cases the mean age of Politburo and Central Committee members in 1968 is almost the same (compare Table 27, page 99, with Table 14, page 72). Hungary has experienced little change as measured by mean age and standard deviation. has remained at the same level but the distribution has Mean age in Bulgaria changed significantly (see Figures 5 and 6, pages 100,101). 99 TABLE 27 MEAN AGE OF POLITBURO MEMBERS AND CANDIDATES BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 54 (SD=6) 58 (SD-9) 51 (SD=7) 50 (SD-6) 1968 54 (N/A) 49 (N/A) 48 (SD-7) 50 (SD-9) Mean age in Czechoslovakia decreased Significantly from 1957 to 1968. This is true for both the Dubcek and Husak Politburos. In Poland the mean age did not change in spite Of the cooptation in 1968 of Stanislaw Kociolek (35), Josef Tejchma (41), and Jan Szydlak (43). Comprehensive economic reform has occurred in the countries with younger Politburo members. Over 30 percent Of the Politburo members in Poland and Bulgaria have a mean age Of 60 or higher as compared with 18 percent and 13 per- cent in Czechoslovakia and Hungary. (The relatively high figure for Czechoslovakia reflects the presence Of Svoboda, certainly no Opponent Of reform.) The mode for Czechoslo- vakia is 40; for the other countries it is 50. Mean age at cooptation is given in Table 28, page 102. Hungary is the only country in which mean age at cooptation was lower for Politburo members than for Central Committee members (see Table 15, page 73). The Hungarian Politburo is not only the youngest in Eastern Enrope, it is also the most homogeneous in terms of age and age at COOpta- tion. It will be interesting to see if it will maintain Percent 50‘ 40+ 30- 20‘ 101 100 A -—————- Bulgaria f'. — ----- Czechoslovakia ; K . ..... Hungary 1' - _ ..... Poland 40 50 60 70+ years Figure 5. Mean Ages of Politburo Members and - Candidates, 1957 Percent 101 60‘ Bulgaria - ------ Czechoslovakia ...... Hungary ----- - Poland 50 J 40J 30' 20« 10‘ .\ ..\ 04 ". 40 50 60 70+ years Figure 6. Mean Ages of Politburo Members and Candidates, 1968 102 TABLE 28 MEAN AGE AT COOPTATION FOR POLITBURO MEMBERS AND CANDIDATES BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 45 (N/A) 50 (SD-ll) 48 (SD=9) 42 (SD84) 1968 52 (SD-11) 49 (SD-9) 41 (SD-6) 48 (SD-8) this distinction. The Polish Politburo, as the figures in Table 28 indicate, was not able to keep mean age low. (Mean age at cooptation for Cabinet members in the United States, by contrast, is about 54.)2 There is virtually no difference in terms of age among elites with technical, administrative, and manpower skills within each country. Elites with control skills are much higher than the mean in all countries except Hungary. Professionals are higher in all countries except Czechoslo— vakia where they are, on the average, ten years below the mean. Party Bureaucrat, as in the Central Committee, was generally lower than other career categories. Military elites in all countries except Hungary were 10 tO 20 years above the mean-—the only military elite on the Hungarian Politburo was 8 years below the mean. Government bureau- crats tended to be Slightly above the mean. In short, Older elites in all Politburos were gen- erally control, military, or professional personnel. Party bureaucrats and elites with technical skills were below the 103 mean. Older "political" elites possess either control or administrative Skills. Revolutionary Activity Revolutionary activity, as might be expected, was more relevant for Politburo than Central Committee members (compare Table 29 with Table 17, page 78). The only excep- tion to this is Czechoslovakia. It is interesting to note that Hungary has changed least in this regard. This is, once again, consistent with Kadar's policy. He is rational- izing the economic system but making few changes in the party apparatuS--as far as we can determine with the kinds Of variables employed here. TABLE 29 REVOLUTIONARY ACTIVITY RELEVANT (IN PERCENT) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP 1957 1968 1957 1969 1957 1968 1957 1968 Not Relevant 0 18 44 77 33 40 11 38 Relevant 100 82 56 23 66 60 89 62 Total 100 100 100 100 99 100 100 100 Minority Career Paths The only country with sizeable minority representa- tion on the Politburo in 1968 is Czechoslovakia. Czechs and Slovaks, as in the case of the Central Committee, exhibit 104 different career and skill attributes. Slovaks rely more on the party apparatuS--64 percent Of the Slovaks are party bureaucrats as opposed to 18 percent of the Czechs. Czechs possess more technical expertise (87 percent) than the Slo- vaks (28 percent). These figures are consistent with our ' understanding Of the situation in Czechoslovakia: the data reflect differences between the two communist parties in r—l terms Of history, personnel, and operational milieu. Summary l The trend towards cooptation of elites with rational E3 skills, which was confirmed in our analysis Of Central Com- mittee members, seems to be influencing cooptation into the Politburo as well. The percentage Of elites with technical educations and technical skills increased significantly in Czechoslovakia and Poland (see Table 31, page 106). Bulgaria also registered sizeable increases but remained low relative to the other countries. The Hungarian Politburo, as the data in Table 30, page 105, indicate, was the most stable of all in terms of variables affecting recruitment patterns. Perhaps the most interesting finding Of this entire study is the stability of the recruitment process in Hungary (see Table 30, page 105, and Table 31, page 106). The Polit- buro and Central Committee Of the HSWP contained the highest percentages Of elites with technical skills in East Europe in 1957. Neither body has experienced much change since 105 TABLE 30 CHANGES IN COMPOSITION--P0LITBUROa BCP 'KSC HSWP PUWP Education Area Agriculture -13 3 0 0 Technical 31 27 6 42 Worker -11 -45 -25 -25 Education/Culture 23 3 14 -25 Health/Social Services 0 3 O 0 Control -18 3 -ll 8 Law 2 - 4 15 -17 Agitation -18 7 0 17 Skills Agriculture - 6 10 14 14 Industry 21 45 -14 36 Administration -13 -34 —14 6 Justice 0 — 3 0 7 Manpower 5 - 3 7 0 Control -17 - 8 3 -59 Foreign Affairs 5 —ll 7 0 Education/Culture 5 0 0 0 Career Government Bureaucrat 0 - 9 7 29 Party Bureaucrat — 4 8 l 36 Mass 15 — 8 8 -20 Professional (Culture) 10 10 7 7 ProfessionalCTechnical) 15 10 0 7 Military -11 3 7 - 6 Non-professional 0 0 -14 0 Militant -29 -15 -14 -53 aPercent added in each category since 1957 minus percent dropped who were members 1957. then. In fact, the only two changes in Hungary, as measured by all my variables, which are statistically significant, are the emergence Of the party bureaucrat career channel and the cooptation Of elites with rational skills ("rational" skills include technical, education, health, social services, and cultural Skills). 106 TABLE 31 SIGNIFICANCE LEVELS FOR x2 TESTS (DROPS AND ADDS ONLY) BCP KSC HSWP PUWP Central Committee Education Area Technical .01 .01 -— __ Education/Health .01 —- —— -_ [Ti Skills 5 ~ Technical (Agriculture ' and Industry) .05 -- __ __ Industry .02 .01 —_ __ Rational (Industry, .~ Health, Education) .01 .02 .05 .02 IE a? Career Professional .02 -— __ __ Party Bureaucrat .01 -— .01 -- Politburo Education Area Technical -- .02 -- .05 Skills Technical -- .001 -- .05 Rational -- .001 -- .05 Career Professional .05 -— __ __ Party Bureaucrat -— —- —- .05 Continuity in the recruitment process, in spite of economic reform (which began in Hungary in 1958), is probably one Of Kidér's greatest assets. Party functionaries are not faced with the Spectre Of a rising crop Of technocrats chal- lenging their positions; elites Of working class origin and with working class experience are still very visible in 107 higher party circles. Kadar faced two problems in 1957-- reconciliation with the masses and gaining the loyalty Of party members, especially the dogmatists who were suspicious Of his liberal tendencies. He appears to have been success- ful on both counts. Decision-making in non-political areas is shared with elites at the Central Committee level and outside the party. The requirements for recruitment to Fe. elite positions have not changed: party elites are young; ' 1 turnover is high; the party has retained its worker bias. The average party functionary cannot help but be reassured J by the continuity of the party in Spite Of changes in the p} economic system. Reform would not appear as threatening as, say, in the case Of Bulgaria where Zhivkov has been promoting younger elites with rational Skills to high party positions.3 Both the Central Committee and the Politburo in Czechoslovakia made Significant changes in requirements for cooptation. The two bodies are now more Similar in terms of background characteristics than they were in 1957. The Central Committee and Politburo both express commitment to the reform program. Unfortunately, the situation is less than ideal for testing hypotheses. The changes in Bulgaria and Poland indicate that elites are aware Of skill requirements for a modernizing society. In these countries, unlike Hungary, it appears that elites with the requisite Skills are being coopted into the Politburos. This approach, assuming the technical elites 108 are more "rational," could ultimately have a greater impact on the party apparatus than Kadar's approach. Rational elites in Bulgaria and Poland are in a position to share in political decision-making. Cooptation of elites with tech— nical skills is more noticeable in the Politburo than the Central Committee in Poland. Changes in recruitment patterns for Politburo members have increased the similarity between the Politburo and Cen— tral Committee in each country. The assumption that the data would reveal two recruitment patterns does not seem to be valid. The "structure Of opportunities" for the two bodies Lj became more similar from 1957 to 1968. All countries have responded to changes in skill requirements by COOpting elites with technical skills. The response has varied from country to country, however. In Hungary, technical elites are COOpted at the Central Committee level but not in the Politburo. In Czechoslovakia they have been COOpted at both levels and the percentage Of elites with technical skills is high at both levels. The percentage in Bulgaria and Poland remains low relative to Hungary and Czechoslovakia and, unlike Hungary, professional-technical elites in Bulgaria and Poland share decision-making power in the Politburo. The Hungarian Party has changed little and retains a strong worker bias. The Bulgarian Party has made substantial changes and has increased its elitist bias. Economic reform will be difficult in Poland and Bulgaria; 109 party elites seem to have decided to maintain complete party control Of economic decision-making but party elites in middle and lower level administrative positions in both countries lack the requisite skills (and, apparently, the diSpositions) to effectuate meaningful reform. Zhivkov, in particular, faces a good deal Of opposition from dogmatists within the party. 3 These conclusions are based on the assumption that Fri elites with rational skills will have a tendency to react "rationally"--that is, not ideologically--to social problems. However, factors other than ideology Often influence decision- J making (e.g., intra-party factional disputes, international politics, influence of non-party elites, public sentiment), and these factors may force "non—rational" decisions on party elites. Our conception Of what is and what is not rational is relative; approaches to problem-solving cannot finally be classified "rational" and "non-rational." What this study has attempted to do is to determine if political leaders are gaining the requisite technical skills to admin- ister an industrializing society. This much we can establish. Whether or not they will react "rationally" (as we define it) is problematical; many factors influence decision—making. The study has tentatively justified this assumption, however, because the parties with the highest percentages of elites with rational skills are taking, or have attempted to take, more realistic approaches to solving problems Of economic development than the parties with fewer technical elites. 110 NOTES 1R. V. Burks, The Dynamics Of Communism in Eastern Europe (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1961). 2Lewis J. Edinger, ed., political Elites in Indus- trialized Societies (New York: Wiley, 1967), p. 289. 3J. F. Brown, The New Eastern Europp (New York: Praeger, 1966), pp. 15—19. CHAPTER V CONCLUSION The hypotheses and findings are summarized at the end Of each chapter. In this chapter, rather than repeating these, I will approach the problem Of elite recruitment from Slightly different vantage points. Fleron's typology will be employed to examine and classify recruitment patterns in Eastern Europe. A brief summary will be made Of general trends in each country. And, finally, the hypotheses pre- sented in Chapter I, which were drawn from studies Of elites in non-communist societies, will be analyzed with the find- ings from this study. According to Fleron, political elites, who do not possess the Skills necessary to manage an industrial economy, have at least four alternative courses Of action: to try to get the Specialized elites to contribute their Skills at no cost, to either retrain members of the political elite or recruit into the system as replacements new cadres with the necessary skills, to COOpt into the system members Of the Specialized elites who possess Skills, or to Share power on a more or less competitive and equal basis as in a pluralist system.1 The latter two recruitment systems, the "cooptative" 111 112 and the "pluralistic," are distinguished by the presence Of professional elites in political Offices. The cooptative system is distinguished from the pluralistic system by the presence Of institutionalized advantage for professional politicians and by the method Of replenishing the political elite. Fleron's analysis Of the USSR led him to conclude that the leadership system is a COOptative system—-that is, specialized professional elites are present in political Offices (which distinguishes it from the monocratic and adaptive systems) and the political elites possess institu- tionalized advantages (which distinguishes it from the plural- istic system). He then goes on to argue that it will be possible for political elites in the USSR to maintain con- trol Of the polity by having access to the Specialized skill requirements necessary for an industrial society without having to compete with the Specialized elites for political power. The elite recruitment systems in Eastern EurOpe are also cooptative. Professional elites are present in each Central Committee and Politburo.2 Political elites in each body possess institutionalized advantages. This is not an adequate description Of the recruit- ment process, however. The comparative approach, which Fleron did not employ, has revealed substantial differences among the countries considered in this study. A brief coun— try-by-country description will illustrate the point. In 113 this analysis only professionals with technical skills will be discussed. Bulgaria, in 1957, had no professionals holding elite positions in the Central Committee and the Politburo. In 1968, there were thirteen professionals in the Central Committee and two in the Politburo. There were, however, elites with technical Skills in both bodies in 1957. Bul- garia, it seems, moved from an adaptive system to a coopta- tive system from 1957 to 1966. Czechoslovakia, in 1957, had thirteen professionals on the Central Committee and none on the PolitburO--the presence Of professionals on the Central Committee is enOugh to classify the system as COOptative. In 1968, there were fifteen professionals on the Central Committee and one on the PolitburO--the system is still cooptative. During the 1957 to 1968 period, however, there was a larger percentage increase in political elites with technical Skills. It seems, in other words, that the system is both adapting and COOpting whereas the Bulgarian system is only COOpting. The recruitment system in Hungary resembles that in Czechoslovakia. In 1957, there were seven professionals in the HSWP Central Committee and none on the Politburo; in 1968 there were eleven professionals on the Central Committee and none on the Politburo. In percentage terms, there was no change, either in representation Of professionals or Of polit- ical elites with technical skills. The recruitment system, in this sense, seems to be at an equilibrium--balanced between 114 COOpted elites with technical skills and political elites with technical Skills or balanced between an adaptive and a COOptative system. There were eight professionals on the 1957 PUWP Central Committee; in 1966 there were seven. While the per- centage Of coopted professionals declined, the percentage Of recruited political elites with technical skills increased in both the Central Committee and the Politburo. The re- cruitment System, it seems, is more adaptive than cooptative. If we adopt as our criterion of "professional" the requirement that elites must be coopted directly from a pro- fessional, non-political status, the picture changes Slight- ly. Poland is still more adaptive than cooptative; Bulgaria, however, is static. Hungary and Czechoslovakia are both adaptive and cooptative——but they change in different ways. It is the party elites in Hungary, and the government elites in Czechoslovakia, who noticeably increase their technical skills. In short, although Fleron's typology provides an alternative to the totalitarian-pluralism dichotomy, it is limited by its definitional requirements. Communist elite recruitment systems coopt and they adapt; it is as important to determine how they are changing as it is to classify them in a particular category. Fleron, it seems, has restricted the explanatory value Of his typology by making his cate- gories mutually exclusive. A giwmlrecruitment system can be classified but there is no way to analyze the dynamic of the 115 system or to adequately compare it with other recruitment systems. For example, is the system more or less cooptative now than it was ten years ago? IS it more or less coopta- tive than another system? Also, it seems necessary and useful to apply these distinctions to various elite bodies within a system. Altering the categories in the typology would make it less precise, perhaps, but the typology would then be more useful in analyzing and comparing elite recruit- ment trends. Elite Recruitment and Economic Change Since 1948, societies in Eastern Europe have been experiencing a period of rapid industrialization. In Chap- ter 11, some Of the ramifications Of this process for the organization and administration Of the economic system were discussed. Economists agree that a centrally administered economic system, making the transition from an extensive to an intensive period Of development, will require changes in organization, administration, and decision-making criteria. It was predicted that these changes would be reflected in elite recruitment patterns. Data presented in the third and fourth chapters sup- port this prediction. Recruitment patterns in Czechoslovakia, the country with the highest level Of economic development in this study, demonstrated the greatest response to changes in skill requirements. Czechoslovakia was also at the 116 forefront in the drive for economic reform. This is certainly not surprising, considering the slowdown in her growth rate and her strong dependence on exports Of high quality goods to Western markets. Ota Sik, who is generally considered to be the architect Of the Czechoslovak reform, concluded that a complete overhaul Of the state economic bureaucracy would be required and that economic decision-making would have to conform to principles of rationality and efficiency. Re- cruitment trends, in both the Central Committee and Polit- buro in Czechoslovakia, indicate a positive response to these criteria. Prior to the 1968 Intervention, political elites in Czechoslovakia appeared quite willing to share decision- making power with non-political elites. Elite recruitment trends in Bulgaria, which is the least developed country in the study, revealed the lowest percentage of individuals with technical expertise of all Central Committees. Bulgaria, like Rumania, has not yet experienced the problems Of a qualitative economic system. Party leaders are aware Of the problems which the more ad- vanced economies are experiencing; economic reforms have been initiated and the percentage Of elites with rational skills is increasing. The kind of response to Changes in skill requirementS—-emphasis on cooptation rather than adapta— tion--indicates that rationalizing elites will probably face serious Opposition from entrenched party and government bureaucrats. 117 It is difficult to rank Poland and Hungary in level of economic development. Statistics indicate that they are quite Similar, although Hungary is slightly higher in most Of the measures Ernst employs. At any rate, they both have entered the qualitative growth period and are experiencing, to a lesser extent, some Of the problems which are plaguing Czechoslovakia. The very different responses of the two parties, as indicated by economic reform and recruitment patterns, have not resulted from differences in level of economic development. Political leaders in both countries have long been aware Of problems in the economic Sphere. Belassa, in his study Of the Hungarian economy, concluded that the "struc- ture Of the Hungarian economy as found in 1956 presented difficulties in the way Of further growth."3 Kadar began to initiate reform measures as early as 1958. The economic reform adopted in 1966 will require a complete reorganization Of the economic system. Recruitment to elite positions reflects the need for technical expertise and rationality in decision—making. The decision-making process in Hungary permits increasing participation by non-political elites. Gomulka, in 1957, created an Economic Council in Poland and charged it with the task Of preparing a blueprint for a new Polish economic model. The Council proposed com- plete reorganization of the economic system. Only minor piecemeal reforms have been implemented, however. The reform program adOpted in 1966 is a very cautious approach, although 118 it seems that a thorough reform is necessary. Elite recruit- ment reflects this cautious approach, the percentage Of elites with rational Skills is increasing but quite Slowly. The party seems reluctant to share decision-making power with non-political specialists, preferring to concentrate on in- creasing the Skill attributes Of party and government bureau— crats. Political elites in the highest party positions are acquiring technical Skill attributes, but at the middle range level the percentage with technical skills remains low. Political considerations still dominate economic decision- making in Poland. It appears as though an economic crisis similar to that in Czechoslovakia may be required to force changes in recruitment patterns and decision-making criteria. Trends in recruitment reveal a constant interplay of politics and economics. Generally speaking, a rise in per- centage Of elites with technical Skills is balanced with an increase in percentage with control skills or an increase in percentage Of party bureaucrats. Intra-party conflicts, about which we have little information, and changes in the internal balance Of power undoubtedly influence recruitment patterns. Thus a graph Of the pattern of cooptation Of rational elites will Show gains and losses within each coun- try and Significant differences among the countries. We still lack an adequate understanding Of the dynamics at work in each party (and in the bloc) to make bold predictions regarding the future of rationality as a governing norm in decision-making. The data revealed positive trends in 119 cOOptation Of elites with rational-technical skills, but it also revealed that, in Spite Of fairly Obvious economic imperatives, the strong role Of ideology and politics fre- quently interrupts and often upsets trends that might be imputed to the need for economic rationalization. Conflicts among rationality, ideology, and politics are far from resolved in Eastern Europe, as events in 1968 illustrated. (These include, for example, the intervention in Czechoslo- vakia and the theme Of the Fifth PUWP Congress, which stressed ideological purity in the face Of serious economic problems.) The Comparative Study Of Elites One of the most conspicuous shortcomings in the field of comparative politics has been the failure Of scholars to bridge the gap between studies Of communist and non-commu— nist societies. The Slow demise of the totalitarian model, which emphasized differences between communist and non-commu— nist societies and similarities among communist societies, is in part responsible. The present study, which has focused on only one aSpect of the developmental process, has under- scored the diversity among communist societies. Our ability to conceptualize, analyze, and explain developmental proc- esses would be greatly enhanced by studies which bridge the conceptual gap between communist and non-communist societies. A comparative analysis of the dynamics Of elite recruitment and elite stratification would make useful contributions, 120 both to the study Of comparative politics and to the study of political development. At the outset of this project some propositions were presented about elite behavior in non-communist societies, propositions which could be analyzed with the findings Of this study. These will be discussed very briefly below. In spite Of problems of conceptualization and comparability, problems which could be reduced in a research design, it is Obvious that a comparative study Of elite behavior would be both enlightening and heuristic. l. Everywhere careers are lengthened, with success coming only after years Of work in Specialized areas. Data on communist elites support this hypothesis. Career lines, in all countries, are more established and Specialized now than they were in 1957. Party bureaucrats are younger, but elites with Special Skills--professionals, mass leaders, foreign affairs specialists--are generally Older in 1966 than they were in 1957. 2. The "structure of opportunities" will be different for minority groups. Recruitment patterns in Eastern Europe definitely support this proposition. Elites from minority groups con- centrate in particular career and skill areas (e.g., Jews in Poland were disproportionately drawn to foreign affairs and the professions; Slovaks relied heavily on the party bureauc- racy in 1966, and professional careers in 1957). Minority 121 elites also participated more in revolutionary activity, and have higher education levels than elites from the dominant ethnic group. 3. Members of the elite strata are becoming Older at success. Age at recruitment, for Central Committee members, changed very little in Eastern Europe from 1957 to 1966. This is not true of the Politburos, however. Age at recruit- ment increased substantially in Bulgaria and Poland from 1957 to 1968. In Czechoslovakia it remained stable, and it declined in Hungary. Political elites are younger now at recruitment than in 1957, while specialized elites are Older. The data, broadly Speaking, support Duverger's hypothesis that "communist elites are able to impose their young upon the party." Thus the elite strata has declined in age in Hungary and Czechoslovakia, remained stable in Bulgaria, and increased slightly in Poland. (Data on the Fifth PUWP Con- gress, held in November 1968, would probably reveal a decline for Poland also.) 4. The elite opportunity structure can be described as hav- ing a number Of peaks, each scalable by Specialized methods. Data on East European elites support this hypothesis. Representatives Of the "peaks" in the Central Committee-- party, government, mass, professional, military, culture-- are distinguished by varying career and skill attributes. 122 These attributes vary from country to country, but within each country the career paths are fairly well established. 5. The trends toward expansion and Specialization will be manifest in all elite pyramids. This study has been concerned with only one elite pyramid—-the party. Data on Central Committees and Polit- buros support the hypothesis, however. Elites were definitely more Specialized in 1966 than in 1957. Represen- tation Of the two non-specialized career paths, non—profes- sional and militant, declined significantly. The percentage of elites with general administrative skills also declined, and there was an increase in percentage Of elites with Spe- cialized Skills (technical, agriculture, social welfare, etc.). The number Of representatives from various "elite pyramids" increased while the number from mass organizations declined, again indicating increased specialization. All the Central Committees and Politburos increased in size. 6. Bureaucratic elites will gain dominance over political elites because of Specialization. The power relationship between political and bureau- cratic elites cannot be ascertained from these data. It is obvious that elites with rational Skills are increasing in percentage representation on elite bodies, and, as Czecho- slovakia. in 1968 indicated, they are probably becoming more powerful vis-a-vis the political elites. The relationship varies from country to country, however, so a general pre- diction would be difficult. Political elites in Hungary, it 123 appears, Share decision-making power with non-political elites. In Czechoslovakia, before the intervention, it was Obvious that non-political elites had increased their in- volvement in the decision-making process. Political elites in Poland and Bulgaria are carefully guarding their power and, barring some unforeseen event, it appears that the in- fluence Of non-political elites will be tightly controlled. In short, while it is apparent that rational elites have improved in their power relationship with the parties in the last decade, it would be impossible to predict that they will gain dominance. Politics and ideology, in communist socie— ties, have not yet taken back seats to economic rationaliza- tion, although the data would seem to indicate that struggles for power are likely tO increase. Prospects for Fature Research This study has stimulated at least as many questions as it has answered. A country-by-country analysis seems essential to discuss the most Obvious questions: Why the different approaches to decision—making? What determines the role and power of technical elites in a communist society? Which social, cultural, historical, geographical variables exert the greatest influence over the developmental process? Why are political elites more willing to share decision- making power in one communist society than another? Under what conditions are rational elites most likely to dominate 124 decision—making? Does the increased involvement of rational elites in political decision-making increase the potential for developing sub—system autonomy? The data in this study provide good starting points for further comparative and country Specific studies. 125 NOTES 1Frederic J. Fleron, Jr., "Cooptation as a Mechanism of Adaptation to Change," Polity, II, 2 (Winter, 1969). 2Fleron's definition of a Specialized elite is dif— ferent from mine, however. A Specialized elite, in his typology, is one who Spent at least seven years in a profes- sional or technical vocation before entering political Office. These individuals were classified as "coopted." A professional elite in my study is defined as having Spent at least half of his career in a professional or technical vocation. Since we would find more specialized elites in Eastern Europe using Fleron's definition than mine, it seems safe to assume that this definitional requirement is satis— fied. 3Bela Belassa, The Hungarian Experience in Economic Planning (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1959), p. 235. BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Alford, Robert. Party and Society. Chicago: Rand McNally, 1963. Almond, Gabriel, and Powell, G. Bingham, Jr. Comparative Politics: A Developmental Approach. Boston: Little,Brown and Company, 1966. Almond, Gabriel, and Verba, Sidney. The Civic Culture. Boston: Little,Brown and Company, 1963. Anonymous. Leading Positions and Personalities in Eastern Euro e. Newark: ‘Intercontinental Press Service, 1957 Armstrong, John A. "Party Bifurcation and Elite Interests," Soviet Studies, XVII (April 1966), 417-430. . The Soviet Bureaucratic Elite. New York: Praeger,‘1959. Aron, Raymond. "Social Structure and the Ruling Class," British Journal Of Sociology, I (1950). Azrael, Jeremy R. Managerial Power and Soviet Politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1966. Barghoorn, Frederick G. Politics in the USSR. Boston: Little,Brown and Company, 1966. Bass, R. "East European Communist Elites--Their Character and History," International Affairs, XX (1966), 106-117. Bauman, Zygmunt. "Economic Growth, Social Structure, Elite Formation: The Case Of Poland," International Social Science Journal, XVI (1964), 203-216. Beck, Carl. Aggregative Career Characteristics Of Eastern European POlitical Leaders. Occasional Paper: Uni- versity Of Pittsburg, 1968. . "Bureaucracy and Political Development in Eastern Europe," in Joseph LaPalombara (ed.), Political 126 127 Bureaucracy and Political Development. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1963. Beck, Carl, and Malloy, James M. Political Elites: A Mode of Analysis. Pittsburg: University of Pittsburg, 1968. Beck, Carl, and McKechnie, John. Political Elites: A Select Computerized Bibliography. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1968. Belassa, Bela. The Hungarian Experience in Economic Plan- ning. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1959. Benjamin, Roger W., and Kautsky, John H. "Communism and Economic Development," American Political Science Review, LXII, l (1968), 110-124. Borkenau, Franz. European Communism. New York: Praeger, 1953. . World Communism. Ann Arbor: University Of Michigan Press, 1962. Bottomore, T. B. Elites and Society. London: C. A. Watts and Company, 1964. Brown, J. F. The New Eastern Europe. New York: Praeger, 1966. . "Reforms in Bulgaria," Problems of Communism, XV, 3 (May—June, 1966), 17—22. Burks, R. V. The Dynamics Of Communism in Eastern Europe. Princeton, NIUT: Princeton University Press, 1961. Campbell, Angus, et a1. Elections and the Political Order. New York: Wiley, 1966. Cornell, Richard. "Comparative Analysis Of Communist Move- ments," Journal Of Politics, XXX, 1 (February 1968), 25‘66 O Dahrendorf, Ralf. Class and Class Conflict in Industrial Society. PalO Alto, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1959. Dallin, Alexander, and Larson, Thomas B. (eds.). Soviet Politics Since Khrushchev. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 1968. Dellin, L. A. D. Bulgaria. New York: Praeger, 1957. 128 Duverger, Maurice. Political Parties. New York: Wiley, Edinger, 1954. Lewis J. (ed.). Political Leadepship in Indus— trialized Societies. New York: Wiley, 1967. "Continuity and Change in the Background of German Decision-Makers," The Western Political Quarterly, XIV, l (1961). "Post-Totalitarian Leadership: Elites in the Edinger, Erlich, Ernst, German Federal Republic," American Political Science Review, LIV, l (1960). Lewis J., and Searing, Donald D. "Social Background in Elite Analysis: A Methodological Inquiry," American Political Science Review, LXI, 2 (June 1967), 428-446. Alexander. "Economic Reforms in Communist Countries," Dissent (May/June, 1967), 311-319. Maurice. "Postwar Economic Growth in Eastern Europe," in New Directions for the Soviet Economy, Part IV. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1966, 873-916. Feiwel, George R. The Economics of a Socialist Enterprise. New York: Praeger, 1965. Feron, Bernard. "Les Tchechoslovaques se dissent contre le centralisme excessif," Le Monde diplomatique (Avril 1968), l. Finkle, Jason L., and Gable, Richard W. (eds.). Political Development and Social Change. New York: Wiley, 1966. Fischer, George. The Soviet System and Modern Society. New Fleron, York: Atherton Press, 1968. Frederic J., Jr. Communist Studies and the Social Sciences. Chicago: Rand McNally, 1969. "Cooptation as a Mechanism Of Adaptation to ‘Change: The Soviet Political Leadership System, " Polity, II, 2 (Winter, 1969). "Note on the Explication of the Concept 'Elite' in the Study Of Soviet Politics," Canadian Slavic Studies, 11, l (1968), 111-115. 129 . "Political Development and the Process Of Indus- trialization in the USSR: The Changing Nature Of the Soviet Political Leadership System," Prepared for delivery at the 134th Annual Meeting of the American Association for the Advancement Of Science, New York, December 28, 1967. . "Soviet Area Studies and the Social Sciences: Some Methodological Problems in Communist Studies," Soviet Studies, XIX, 3 (January 1968), 313-339. "The Soviet Political Elite: Aspects of Political and Economic Development in the USSR," Paper presented at the 1968 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., September 2—7. . "Toward a Reconceptualization Of Political Change in the Soviet Union," Comparative Politics, 1, 2 (1969), 228-244. Gamarnikow, Michael. Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe. Detroit: Wayne State University Press, 1968. . "New Trends in East European Trade Unionism," East Europe, XVIII, 6 (June 1968), 13-18. Gehlen, Michael P., and McBride, Michael, "The Soviet Central Committee: An Elite Analysis," American Political Science Review, LXII, 4 (December 1968), 1232—1241. Greene, Thomas H. "The Communist Parties Of Italy and France: A Study in Comparative Communism," World Politics, XXI, 1 (October 1968), 1-39. Griffith, William E. (ed.). Communism in Europe. Cambridge: MIT Press, I (1964), II (1966). Grossman, Gregory. "Economic Reforms: A Balance Sheet," Problems Of Communism, XV, 6 (November—December, 1966), 43-55. Grossman, Gregory (ed.). value and Plan: Economic Calcula— tion and Orgepization ififiEESterniEfirope. LOS‘Angeles: University Of California Press, 1960. Hodnett, Grey. "The Obkom First Secretaries," Slavic Review, XXIV (December 1965), 36-52. Hough, Jerry. "The Soviet Elite: In Whose Hands the Future?" Problems Of Communism, XVI, 2 (March- April, 1967), 18-26. 130 Ionescu, Ghita. The Politics of the EurOpean Communist States. New York: Praeger, 1967. Communism in Rumania. London: Oxford, 1964. Jacobs, Dan N. (ed.). The New Communisms. New York: Harper and Row, 1969. Kala, John. "The Bulgarian Economy," Survey (London), NO. 39 (December 1961). Kautsky, John H. gemmunism and the Politics Of Development. New York: Wiley, 1968. Keller, Suzanne. Beyond the Ruling Class. New York: Random House, 1963. Kecskemeti, Paul. The Unexpected Revolution. Palo Alto, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1961. Knight, Maxwell. The German Executive, 1890-1933. Palo Alto, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1952. Korbonski, Andrezej. Politics Of Socialist Agriculture in Poland. New York: ‘COIBmBia University Press, 1965. Kubat, Daniel. "Patterns Of Leadership in a Communist State--Czechoslovakia, 1948-1956," Journal of Cen— tral European Affairs, XXI (1961), 305—318. Kuhn, Heinrich. Biographisches Handbuch der Tscherhoslovakia (Vollegium Carolinum Veroffenthlchunger) Verlag Robert Lerche, Munchen, 1961. Lange, Oskar. Problems of Political Economy Of Socialism. Warsaw, 1958. Lasswell, Harold, and Lerner, Daniel. World Revolutionapy Elites. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1965. Lerner, Daniel. "The Nazi Elite," in Lasswell and Lerner, World Revolutionarp Elites, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1965. Lipset, S. M. Political Man. New York: Doubleday, 1959. Lipset, S. M., and Rokkan, Stein (eds.). Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross National PerSpectives. New York: The Free Press, 1967} Lodge, Milton. "Soviet Elite Participatory Attitudes in the Post-Stalin Period," American Political Science Review, LXII (September 1968), 827-840. 131 Marcuse, Herbert. Soviet Marxism. New York: Columbia University Press, 1958. Marvick, Dwaine. Political Decision—Makers. New York: The Free Press, 1961. Matthews, Donald R. The Social Background of Political Decision—Makers. New York: DOubleday, 1954. . U.S. Senators and Their World. New York: Vintage Press, 1960. Meissner, Boris. "Totalitarian Rule and Social Change," Problems of Communism, XV, 6 (November-December, 1966), 56-61. Meyer, Alfred G. The Soviet Political System. New York: Random House, 1965. . "Authority in Communist Political Systems," in Lewis Edinger (ed.), Political Leaderspip in Indus— trialized Societies. New York: John Wiley, 1967. . "Symposium on Comparative Politics," Slavic Review, XXVI, l (1967), 1-29. Michael, Jan M. Central Plenning in Czechoslovakia. Palo Alto, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1960. Montias, John M. Central Planning in Poland. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1962. Moore, Barrington, Jr. Terror and Progress in the USSR. New York: Harper and Row, 1954. Parry, Geraint. Political Elites. New York: Praeger, 1969. Ploss, Sidney. Conflict and Decision-Making in Soviet Russia. Princeton: Prihceton‘UhiVersiiy Press, 1965. Powell, Elizabeth. Dynamics of Elite Recruitment--The Cases Of the Soviet Unionp Belgaria and Czechoslovakia. Unpublished Master's Thesis, University of Georgia, 1969. Pryer, Frederick C. The Communist Foreign Trade System. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1963. Radio Free Europe. "Biographies of New Politburo Members and Central Committee Secretaries," Poland (October 20, 1968). 132 "Communist Party-Government Line-Up," Eastern Europe and the USSR (1968). "The Czechoslovak Party Congress: A Summing Up" (June 13, 1966). "Eastern Europe's Communist Leaders, V. Bulgaria" (September 1, 1966). . "Eastern EurOpe'S Communist Leaders, IV. Czecho- slovakia" (September 1, 1966). . "Eastern Europe's Communist Leaders, III. Hungary" (September 1, 1966). "Eastern Europe's Communist Leaders, 11. Poland" (September 1, 1966). . "The New Central Committee of the Bulgarian Com- munist Party" (December 14, 1966). . "New Czechoslovak Communist Party Central Commit- tee" (June 14, 1966). . "The New Central Committee of the Hungarian Com- munist Party" (February 6, 1967). Ranney, Austin. Pathways to Parliament. Madison: Univer- sity Of Wisconsin Press, 1965. Rigby, T. H. Communist Party Membership in the USSR--l9l7- 1967. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1968. Rodnick, D. and E. "Notes on Personality Types in Czecho- Slovakia," Public Opinion Quarterly, XIV (1950), 81—88. Rothschild, J. The Communist Party Of Bulgaria. New York: Columbia University Press, 1959. Rubenstein, Alvin Z. (ed.). Communist Political Systems. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 1966. Scalapino, Robert. The Communist Revolution in Asia. Englewood Cliffs: PrentiCe-Hall, 1965. Schlesinger, Joseph. Ambition and Politics: Political Careers in the United States. ChiCago: Rand McNally, 1966. Schueller, George K. "The Politburo," in Lasswell and Lerner (eds.), World Revolutionary Elites. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1965. 133 Schwartz, Joel J., and Keech, William. "Group Influence and the Policy Process in the Soviet Union," American Political Science Review, LXII, 3 (September 1968), 840-852. Searing, Donald D. "The Comparative Study of Elite Social- ization," Comparative Political Studies, I, 4 (January 1969), 471-501. Sharlet, Robert S. "Systematic Political Science and Com— munist Systems," Slavic Review, XXVI, 1 (1967). Shoup, Paul. "Comparing Communist Nations: PrOSpects for an Empirical Approach," American Political Science Review, LXII, 1 (1968), 185-205. Sik, Ota. Plan and Market Under Socialism. White Plains, N.Y.: International Arts and Sciences Press, 1967. Skilling, H. Gordon. "Interest Groups and Communist Poli- tics," World Politics, XVIII (1966), 435-451. . The Governments Of Communist East EurOpe. New York: Crowell] 1966. . "Soviet and Communist Politics, A Comparative Approach," Journal of Politics, XXII (1960), 300-313. Sorokin, G. M. "Basic Trends of Economic Development in the Socialist Countries Of Europe," in M. C. Kaser (ed.), Economic Development for Eastern Europe. New York: Macmillan, 1968. Spulber, Nicolas. The State and Economic Development in Eastern Europe. New York: Random House, 1966. Staar, Richard F. "The Central Committee Of the United Polish Worker's Party," Journal Of Central European Affairs, XVI (1957), 371-383. Tarrow, Sidney. Peasant Communism in Southern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1967. "Political Dualism and Italian Communism," Amer- ican Political Science Review, LXII, l (1967). Tatu, Michael. "La Session Du Comité Central Renforce Le Camp Des Partisans D'une Democratisation Modérée," Le Monde ( Avril 4, 1968), 5. "Le Comité Central a remanié profondément 1a direction du parti Communiste," Le Monde (Avril 6, 1968), 5. 134 Tomasic, D. "Political Leadership in Contemporary Poland," Journal Of Human Relations, IX (1961), 191-205. . "The Rumanian Communist Leadership," Slavic Review, XX (1961), 477-494. Tucker, Robert C. "On the Comparative Study Of Communism," World Politics, XIX, 2 (January 1967), 242-258- Wellisz, Stanislaw. The Economics Of the Socialist Bloc. New York: McGraw Hill, 1964. Zauberman, Alfred. Industrial Progress in Poland, Czecho- Slovakia, and East Germany, 1937-1962. New York: Oxford University Piess, 1964.