Illlllll'llllll Illllllllllllllllll THESIS 3 12930 01089 3893 1513.52.43; estate ' University I‘ , A 'pff-Tlf‘vr This is to certify that the thesis entitled An Inquiry Into the Prediction of Mergers Using Discriminate Analysis On Financial Ratios presented by David C. Distad has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. Finance _ degree in é// Date 7M7X} Major professor 0-7 639 MSU LIBRARIES .—;—_ RETURNING MATERIALS: Place in book drop to remove this checkout from your record. FINES will be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. #3565 19;: 'Ht ’ AN INQUIRY INTO THE manrc'rrm OFMEGES USING DISCRIMINANT WEBB on THE FINAICIAL RATICB 0F ACQUIRED FMS by David Charles Disbad ". .'- . '01} mm“ ‘93: L"; .'.‘ ‘- '- ,. -' x - . ->.-, in"..’"! #1:, RN” avfi‘i‘a". r, _. . .. 3", , ,r -; ‘ vv “”0 ‘ mm C“. “‘2‘ "\“t"‘ ‘ " \r 7 ' ‘ ; _I - - 2‘)?" _.‘_.v£lue Of the “8' "l "" ,_, 4:” . . '-,S?~~"J Q’I‘CPa‘fifi thy)??? '74 5,12; s , l u- u- '--’ . . ”-‘y '31” 7”. 197%. A DWATIQW ”plea Here" n. 2'. . . ‘m- 311-1171;! to Azmred-trm 2mm .. w?" .‘ a1 fulfillment of the acquit-cents M from the marsh mutter . {woe V .V‘ l':( 1' yr ~ LAW-143' ‘ ABSTRACT AN INQUIRY INTO 'JIHE PREDICTION OF lemmas USING DISCRIMINANT ANALYSIS 0N FINAICIAL RATIOS .,~< by David Charles Distad :1”; F11» Wombat the history of mergers in the United States, share 5‘ cs3praniuns awarded to existing shareholders have exceeded market 1 .31‘ :38. Because of the contradiction between share praniuns and the i 1 “' "i 1". M”sting value of the acquisition and because of the increasing snphasis .1.“ .b 1 k‘ corporate growth through acquisition, it is appropriate to study ‘ m the 19703. ‘ "re " . ”Wanna were extracted from the Compustat data bases. may .. t1; rid-hmrdred-thirty—five firms acquired in the period 1970- ‘211 lute iron the same time span for three-Inmdred-twenty-three 153-. ‘ silt-figured as of July, 1981. 3. Fifty films acquired in 1979. Wred-forty—flve unacquired firms as a control group for A A gent" My addressed financial characteristics presuming a ‘Zasqutsition's attributes are reflected in its financial David (harles Distad statements. his study incorporated financial information to three years preceding acquisition. 'Nenty types of accounting information were used to calculate thirty-seven financial ratios for each firm in the first two samples. 'mose ratios were used to calculate three discriminant functions. Multivariate discriminant analysis (MDA), an acceptable statistical procedure for these applications was used. Next, the nunber of ratios used in the discriminant functions was reduced, but attempts to reduce the nunber of ratios below thirteen impaired the models' ability to classify firms correctly. All three models separated firms better than by an other process at high statistical levels of significance in the ex post tests. Acquired firms tended to have greater than average operating incane profitability ratios, but lower than average after-tax ratios. mey were slightly more levered but, cash to interest expenses was more important than any of the leverage ratios. Liquidity and asset activity ratios here generally insignificant. The MBA models were used ex—ante to predict merged firms fran those fifty firms fran Sample 3. Preliminary evidence suggests ratios canmt be used to predict mergers, however, prediction success rates are highest using financial information three years prior to a finn's acquisition. Finally, equal sample sizes fran wples three and four produce high statistically significant positive results for the ex ante model. ACKNOWIEM’IEITS I wish to thank the members of 11w thesis committee, Professors Allen Grunewald, Myles Delano and Jeffrey Towle for their contributions to this research. I especially wish to thank Professor Grunewald whose interest, encouragement, and enthusiasm were of great help to me. I also wish to thank Dr. David Gabhart at Michigan State University who was very helpful to me in the initial stages of this study. Much of the research was canpleted at California State University at Hayward. There, I am indebted to Peter Chamberlin, the computer applications faculty liaison, who wrote my computer programs. Also at Hayward, I would like to thank Professor Craig Johnson, who reviewed early versions of the first three chapters. I also wish to thank the administration at (BUH for various financial awards to help canplete this. Most of this paper was written when I was a visiting lecturer at the University of Michigan. I wish to thank the administration of their graduate school of business for their support, and there I wish to thank Cheryl Strickland who typed most of the first manuscript. Finally, I wish to thank my wife Cynthia for her support over these manymonths, an! to my children, Eric and Annie, whose presence provided the hunor and the sense of urgency required to canplete something of this scale. 11 TABLE OF CONTENTS page 1 ListofTables.......... ........... ...vi '1 Introduction. . . . . . . ....... . ....... . . . 1 Chapter I: Hypotheses and Their Significance . . . . . . . . 3 Chapter II: he Theory Underlying The Hypotheses . ..... 6 A. Managerial Theory . . . ....... . . . ..... 6 B. Monopolistic Theory . . . . ......... . . . . 6 C. Efficiency Considerations and Synergy . . . ..... 7 1. Operating Effects ..... . . . ........ 7 2.MarketShareEffects.. ...... 9 3- Financial Effects . ........ . . . . . . . 10 a. CorporateDethapacity...........10 b. Undervalued Assets — Tobin's q ..... . . c. Accounting Treaiment of Mergers . ...... d. Price-EarningsRatios........... 16 4-ConglanerateEffects...............l7 a. Foreign Acquisitions. . . . . . . . . . . . . D. Managerial Theory - A Review of the Literature. . . . 20 c o [\J U'I E. Siareholder Returns - A Review of the Literature. F. COHClUSiOIl. o c I o c u o c o ...... o o o o o c 31 ChapterIII:'JhePlanofResearch.............. ’40 A. Rationale Fbr The Use of Financial Ratios . . . . . . ”0 iii t 0 I (ma III (Contimxad) page I RatiosIncluiedInThisStmy............"2 ? as f I Etionale For he the of A Discriminant Emotion. " Statistical Limitations or This Stuiy . . . . . . . . “3 mtionale for a Dimension Redmtion . . . . . . . . . "9 ; anter Iv: Data AnalysisandSanple Design. . . . . . . . . 54 A.IhtaSelection....................5’4 D. CharacteristicsoftheData............. 69 T ‘Glapterv: FindingsoftheStuiy.............. 71 ’A.‘ Distad's Reduced Dimension Model Using Discriminant i Analysis.......................71 B. Distad's Reduced Dimension Model Using Rector C. Analysis of Stevens' Factor Analysis Procedures . . . 82 ”- Distad—Stevens Comprisons of Results Using Easter .‘9Analysis.......................93 E: WE RepliestionoftheStevmsl/bdels.........: 95 A ‘u‘ir. Analysis of the Simkowitz-Monroel‘liodel. . . . . . . .111 ‘ Riff-G. 00nc1usion......................1114 a VI: Validation of Mtivariate Discriminant 1;. Malysis....................118 I Jill: Implications of ihis deel and Its Uses . . . . 123 1v f ‘T Q W . YW- .“ ‘ ‘Hr' adapt, or VII (Continued) page 2. Dista's was C O O I U 0 C I O I O O I I I O I 125 ‘ BC 001101151011. 0 o o o o o o o o o I o I o o o o o o l I 135 i “ ~ ‘ mapter VIII: Conclusions ard Evaluations, Limitations and " Future ksearch Suggestions. . . . . . . . . .138 A A. StmaryoffllleResultsofThisStlfly.........138 ! B. PredictionofMergers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .1"? C. Confirmation of Ratio mpotheses. . . . . . . . . . . 153 t D. Statistical Significance of the Models. . . . . . . . 157 I. E.DimensionReduction.................157 A; 1.FactorAnalysis.................158 ‘ if}. A 2. Sequential Univariate Analysis. . . . . . . . . .158 2 r.RetioSeleotionorer-Time..............159 ‘ ~I}.Idmitetions.....................160 i Futm'eResearchSuggestions.............150 LIST OF TABIES RatiosSttfiied.............. Additional htios Studied . . . . . . . . Fisher‘s Boa: M Test for Equal Covariances Classification Results — Hold Olt Group, Split Sanple Validation, LAG 2. . . . . . Classification Resflts - Hold Olt Group, Split Sanple Analysis and Validation, IAG1 Classification Results - Hold Out Group, Split Sample Analysis and Validation, IAGO Descriptive Statistics, Method Direct, Standardized Coefficients . . . . . . . . Sine (tiaracteristies Comparisons, Merged ardlbn—mergedFirms........... Mined Dimension Descriptive Statistics, Standamdized Coefficients . . . . . . . . Dis-tars Redmed Dimension Discriminant groutinmezn........... ,_‘ QMM'ES Mmed Dimension Discriminant it‘mon,ne1............. . l . ~w3'sfbdmed Emulsion Discriminant vi Page ”3 1:5 60 61 65 66 66 68 69 72 73 7a 5—3 (a) - 5-3 (b) 5-3 (c) Fianctim,IAGO.............. Factor Analysis, Eigenvalms, Percent of Variame,IAGO.............. Easter Analysis, Eigenvalues, Percent of Variance,IAG1.............. Factor Analysis, Eigenvalues, Percent of Variance,IAG2.............. First Factor Factor Ioadings, IAG O . . . . Stevens' Factor - Percent of Variance 'Jhble. Distad's 19705 {Best Factor loadings Per FinanciallhtioByBactor,IAGO . . . . . Dietad's 197% Test Factor Loading Per Fimncial Iatio DyFactor, IAG1 . . . . . Distad's 1970s 'Iest Factor Ioadirm Per Financial Ratio HyFactor, IAGZ . . . . . Stevens' Factor Characteristics Compared to Distad's Factor Characteristics, LAG O. . . Final MDA ani Factor Analysis Key Ibtios Compared, (Fran Gables 5-1 and 5-6), IAG o. EDA: Classificatim Matrix, Cbserved I'W30.000looooeoooooooo Distal Ep‘lication of Stevms' Coefficients Shevm' New Classification of Pbrger Groups. _. Wim'efflvpe I ani II Error levels . Mention lattices for,_Stevens' ,4? '- Ir'; .1 .3. P411, . V11 ‘ :3: V Page 75 78 79 80 81 8h 86 89 91 93 91! 96 97 102 103 }' fbfomulatedrlbdel............... I ', 5—16 Stevens' Coefficient Comparison . . . . . . . . . 5-17 81:13va Model vs. Distad's Replication Results 6-1 (a) Distad's 1970 Data Test: Univariate Tests of l \ ' Significance on m Selected Key Financial l'r'. Ratios,IAG2................. 1 "‘L 6-1 (b) Distad‘s 1970 Data 'Dest: Univariate ’Uests of " ZR"- ‘ Significance on MDA Selected Key Financial Ratios,IAG1................. 8241 (c) Distad's 1970 Data Test: Univariate Tests of 'I ‘ l Significance on IVHJA Selected Key Financial Ratios,IAGO................. 6-2 Key Ratios Selected Using Univariate F {Bests Significantat.05 .............. 7-1 (a) Success Rates From Ex Ante Prediction Models - Stevens' Original Model. . . . . . . . 7-1 (19) Success Rates From n: Ante Prediction Models - Stevens' Rsfomulated Model. : 7—1 (c) Success Fates From Ex Ante Rediction I Lbdels-Stevens' Article Model . . . . . . . . Success Rates Ran E: Ante Prediction ‘ Models - Distad's Models - Reduced Dimension. . g 1(9) Success Rates Iii-cm Ex Ante Prediction Models-MethodDirect............. 3‘ gl E; into classification Resnts, Distad's Reduced 4: , . viii DimensionModel,IAG2,1976............130 7-2 (b) Ex Ante Classification Results, Distad's Reduced DimensionModel, IAG1,19'T7. . . . . . . . . . . . 131 7-2 (c) Ex Ante Classification Results, Distad's Reduced DimensionModel,IAGO,1978. . . . . . . . . . . . 132 7-3 Bypofiietical Classification thtrix, LAG 2, i! ,. Asauning a 94.6% Maximun Chance Rate, and a 1005 1‘ Success Rate Predicting Nbrged Firms. . . . . . . . 131l ' 7-4 Hypothetical Enlarged Sample Classification mun, IAG 2 U C I O O U I O I I O O O O O O O I O 135 1 I 1 1 1 l 881 (a) Final. Classification thrices, LAG 2. . . . . . . . 1119 ' 8-1-1 (11) Final Classification Vatrices, IAG 1. . . . . . . . 150 '- ‘\ 5—.1 (c) Final Classification tatrioes, IAG 0. . . . . . . . 150 ix INTRODUC TION Elle purpose of this study is to generate a set of models which will predict mergers. ’Jhis will be accanplished using publicly available data to develop a financial profile of firms more likely to be acquired in subsequent time periods. The financial profile will be developed using multi—variate discriminant analysis (MDA) . In previous studies researchers have found that MDA provides better predictors for such events as banln'uptcies, credit rating, bond ratings, and mergers than the analysis of individual financial ratios analyzed sequentially, in other words, univariate analysis. Throughout the history of mergers in the United States, share price premiums awarded to existirg shareholders of the cannon stocks of target firms have been large, usually in excess of 25% [1 ,4,22]. In recent years that preniun has increased particularly when a target firm has been the object of a bidding contest between two or more potential acquirers [51]. Moreover, a dramatic increase in the nunber of mergers has been occurring. Finally, the nunber of large firms, whether measured by sales or by total assets is increasing [51]. Because of the apparent contradiction between share premiuns of acquisitions and the theoretical value of the firm, and because of the increased anphasis on corporate growth by acquisition in the last twenty years, it is appropriate to conduct a study of mergers. Any technique 1 2 able to predict mergers will be of great benefit to managanents either as an invesiment aid in identifying potential acquisitions, or to assist a firm in exposing its weaknesses in sufficient time to correct the deficiencies am prepare a defense against its future acquisition. In the event that merger candidates can be identified prior to their share price appreciation, rewards to investors would be of considerable magnitude. Perhaps of as much importance such a predicting model would have implications for the existing literature on the seni—strong form of the efficient markets hypothesis. Toe ability to predict mergers would open the possibility of risk arbitrage and risk adjusted excess returns. Finally, models of this nature maybe useful to regulators in anti-trust litigation because of the information provided regarding the capital structures, profit margins, and rates of return on equity or assets employed of both acquirers and acquisitions. Any contributions of this nature would in turn be of benefit to the public. CHAPTER I HYPOTHESFS AND THEIR SIGNH‘ICANCE This dissertation defines a set of ratios which is useful in identifying those firms most likely to be acquired at sane future time. Previous studies [118,135] have not always provided clear results. Different studies have produced contradicting sets of most important ratios.1 Furthermore, the possibility may exist that the set of most predictive ratios can change over time, independent of econcmic factors.2 One critic suggests the results of one test had substantially less financial significance than statistical signficance.3 Much of the literature and empirical work on mergers was done during tin 1960s. Enpirical studies were generally characterized by anall sample sizes. There have also been changes in accounting rules regarding mergers. Acquiring firms, prior to the enactnent of AFB 15, were not required to calculate a fully diluted earnings per share reflecting the coumon stock equivalents (convertible preferred and convertible debentures) so commonly used in the 1960s to finance mergers. Iewellen,4 Nielsen and Mel icher5 and others6 believe that merger preniuns and valuations have changed significantly in the ensuing years. Finally, it appears that with the exception of Singh's [20] study of mergers in the United Kingdom, no studies on industry 1Footnotes appear at the end of each chapter. 3 M characteristics of acquired firms have been conducted. CL‘ne pertinent questions are: 1 . "Are there characteristics prevalent within certain industries which make them more susceptible to takeover?", and 2. "Can these characteristics be identified using this statistical methodolog on financial ratios?" The intent of this study is to provide timely insights into these issues and to resolve confl icts where possible. Ellie methodolog of this study extends the prior literature in that new data, much larger sample sizes, and new ratios are enployed. Fran this, new evidence will develop as to which ratios are most important in predicting mergers, is there any continuity of a best set of ratios over different time spans, and finally, are there any identifiable industry characteristics? Evidence fran earlier literature, to be discussed in the next chapter, suggests that acquired firms are likely to have excess liquidity, unutilized debt capacity, possess favorable earnings prospects, and tend to be priced at lower levels relative to their book value per share, than are unacquired firms. Another null hypothesis in this study is that an MDA designed ratio analysis can not assist in the prediction of mergers. Footnotes Chapter I For exanple consider the conflicting evidence as to the importance of price-earnings ratios and dividend payout percentages found in Michael Simkowitz and Robert Monroe, "A Discriminant Analysis Fimction For Conglanerate Targets, " Southern Journal of Business (Novenber, 1971): 13, and Donald Stev "Financial Characteristics of Merged Firms, A Multivariate Analysis," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 8 (Nb.rch,19T5):1SZ. Donald L. Stevens, "A Multivariate Analysis of Financial Characteristics of Acquired Firms in Industrial Mergers, " (Ph. D. dissertation, Michigan State University, 1972)' 116. Robert J. Monroe, "Comment: Financial Characteristics of Phrged Firms: A Multivariate Analysis," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 8 (March, 1973): 164. Wilbur G. Iewellen, "A Pure Financial Rationale for the Conglanerate Merger," Journal of Finance 26 (Play, 1971): 523. Janes F. Nielsen and Ronald W. Melicher, "Financial Analysis of Acquisition and Merger Premiuns," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 8 (March, 1973): 139, 146 'ihree articles are of interest here. They are: H. Kent Bker, Thanas 0. Miller, and Brian J. Ransparger, "An Inside Look)at Corporate Mergers and Acquisitions," IVSU Topics 829 (Winter, 1%1 4967. Iewis Bernard, "What We Learned Fran 'Ihe Great Merger Frenzy," Fortune, April, 1973. PP. 70-73, 144, 148—150. "Ira Harris: Chicago's Big Dealmaker," Business Week, June 25, 1979, m' 70.78- CHAPTER II THE 1mm UNDERLYING THE HYPOTHEBES There are no universally accepted reasons why firms acquire other firms. The reasons are not always obvious because desired objectives are often unfulfilled, or because the premiun paid for the acquisition exceeded the desired gains.ll However, separating mergers according to general theories of mergers is useful in explaining the process. There are three motives for a merger most commonly described in the literature: [1, 3]. A. Ma__n_a&rial Theory2 This theory holds that . . . the interests of the stockholders are subordinated to the managers who control firms and who seek growth maximization which in turn maximizes the salaries and enolments of managers. This managerial theory predicts that merger activity should have. an unfavorable impact 3on the market values of the securltles of acquiring firms. If the managerial theory has validity it has mad or ramifications in merger literature. Because of its importance an extensive review of the literature is provided in a later section of this chapter for each theory. B. Monopglistic Theog This theory predicts that either or both of the acquiring and acquired firms should benefit from mergers. Here the maj or issues are 6 whether the public is served econanically and socially, and do the pranised benefits accrue to both of the firms? C. Efficiency Considerations and Synergy Generally, any canbination of assets producing a new firm whose value is greater than the sum of the values of the pre—merged firms produces a synergy, which may be attributable to any nunber of considerations including portfolio effects. These considerations may be categorized as: 1. Operating Effects 2. Market Share Effects 3. Financial Effects 4. Conglanerate Effects 1. firatig effects The most commonly cited motive is that a merger will produce a "fit" between two canpanies. An example might be two similar firms; the first has strong production capabilities; the second has strong research capabilities. The canbination of the two firms produces a canpany strong in both areas, and hence potentially stronger than the sum of its parts. Another operating effect involves the use of factors of production. For example, in manufacturing operations, larger firms produce longer, more efficient production, and increasing returns to scale. While both of these exanples are forms of horizontal mergers, operational efficiencies also are found in vertical mergers. Vertical mergers enable canpnies to acquire others at different levels in the distribution chain of a given iniustry. An example is an oil refinery 8 acquiring a chain of service stations, thereby extending its control over the flow of a product to the consuner. Two other operational effects, management and tax considerations are included in Alberts' discussion of bargains which encourage merger activity. rihey are poor forecasts by existing management and inaccurate cost of capital measurenents. Alberta argues the ability to use operational effects in bargaining may affect the price of the acquisition, particularly if the shares are thinly traded.4 Whmgenent bargains abound because, in the absence of any other information, firms are valued under the expectation that the existing management will remain in control. If the managenent of firm X is superior to the managenent of firm Y, then Y' s efficiency should improve after it is acquired by X, which in fact was observed by Mandelker.‘5 Copeland and Weston6 and Iewellen7 suggest that firms most likely to be identified as misrnanaganent bargains would be within the same industry, because managers there would be more capable of detecting less-than—full performance by the other firm's managenent. Misnanaganent bargains are not restricted to horizontal mergers; in practice, they may be vertical or conglomerate mergers. Two other operationm. effects are tax effects of mergers and the value of accunulated tax losses. With regard to the former :8 One such tax consideration is to substitute capital gains taxes for ordinary incane taxes by acquiring a growth firm with a snall or no dividend payout and then selling it to recognize capital gains. Also, when the growth of a firm has slowed so that earnings retention cannot be justified to the Internal Revenue Service, an incentive for sale to another firm is created. Rather than pay out future earnings as dividends subject to the ordinary personal incane tax, future earnings can be capitalized in a sale to another firm. Most substantial mergers are tax-free exchanges. Not only is a lower capital gains tax 9 applicable, but it is also postponed until the securities received in the tax-free exchange are liquidated for cash. (lice the assumptions of perfect capital markets are lifted, individuals or firms may have difficulty selling their tax losses in the marketplace. If losses are not salable in the market, then a merger allows a firm with substantial losses to benefit immediately fran the loss (by cancelling the loss against the profits 0 a profitable firm with which the losing firm has merged) .~ 2. Market Share and Market Power Effects These motives for mergers are not as clearly defensible as operating effects, for a nunber of reasons. Manne, in citing Supreme Court Ruling, questions any merger between carpeting firms, suggesting they are " . . . at least suspect and perhaps per se illegal. The latter result seens especially likely when one of the canbining firms already occupies a substantial position in the relevant market."10 He concedes an econanic interpretation of the failing firm defense is that a firm's tendency toward bankruptcy suggests it is no longer a canpetitor. A failing firm defense of a merger is, " . . . a civilized alternative to bankruptcy . . . that transfers assets from falling to rising firms."11 The consensus of the courts and many econanists is, " . . . there are no important econanies of scale [that] can be attained through a [horizontal] merger which cannot be gained either by internal growth or, at worst, by a cartel, if that were legal."12 Furthermore: Takeovers of corporations are too expensive generally to mks the 'purchase' of managenent canpensation an attractive proposition. It is far more likely that a second kind of reward provides the primary motivation for most take—over attempts. The market price of shares does more than measure the price at which the normal canpensation of executives can be sold to new individuals. mare price . . . measures the potential gain inherent in the cannon 10 stock. 'Jhe lower the stock price, relative to what it could be with more efficient managenent, the more attractive the takeover becomes . . . and the potential return from successful takeovers and revitalization of a poorly run canpnycanbeenormws. . . . we cansee how. . . taking over control of badly run corporations is one of the most impor t 'get rich quick' opportunities in our econany today. 3. Financial Effects of ‘Mergrs a. Comrate Debt Capacity The financial consideration most conmonly cited for mergers involves the alteration of an acquiring firm's existing debt structure and the resulting reduced probability of bankruptcy. Lintner14 found mergers beneficial for four reasons: (1) reduction of the lender's risk in bankruptcy losses, (2) reduction of scale diseconcmies in credit investigations of what was formerly a snaller finn, (3) lowering flotation costs of public issues enhancing their marketability, and (4) producing combined larger issues of debt.14 Elidence exists that one of the most important factors influencing the quality of a bond rating is the size of the offering,15 which provides sane support for Lintner's fourth rationale for mergers. Concurring, Iewellen believed the increased size of the combined firm, in conjunction with a reduced joint probability of failure, would create additional debt capacity, and lower lenders' risks. {The latter should result in lower interest rates, assuning that ratings agencies perceive the reduction in risk.16 Copeland and Weston attack Iewellen's logic: While reducing the unused debt capacity will increase the value of the firm, it has not been established that a merger is the necessary and only method capable of bringing about this method. [the firm with the unused debt capacity is perfectly able to increase the anount of its borrowing without the merger. 7 ll Replying to Copeland and Weston, Ihley and Schall contend: If the merger reduces the variability (uncertainty) of firm cash flow, the newly merged firm may wish to raise its total debt above the total debt of the urmerged firms. 'Ihe merged firm will set its debt at the level which maximizes firm value, and this level of debt will pgten be higher than the total debt of the premerger firms. Copeland and Weston also fail to discuss excessively leveraged firms. As Stevens indicates: . . . in the case of the acquiring firm with excess debt, the merger would lower financial risk and move the new £11161 in the direction of an optimun capital structure. b. Undervalued Assets - Tobin's q Mergers are often undertaken because a potential acquirer believes the market misvalues the assets of a possible acquisition. 'Ihe hypothesized misvaluation may be due to unusually large anounts of cash, unutilized debt capacity, or future cash inflows estimates perceived by the potential acquirer to be different than market estimates. Ratios should assist the potential acquirer in the screening process to find those firms possessing the above attributes or any other quantitative attributes deaned to be important by the acquirer. In the last few years more emphasis has been placed on the possibility of asset misvalmtions. 'Ihe misvaluation contention is that the acquirer will be \mable to build new facilities, whether it be an asset or an entire canpany for a canparable price; that the market V9113 of an acquisition is less than its replacanent cost. Any mergers stuiy should address the misvaluation problen, and this stuiy has done so, by testing thirty seven ratios assessing liquidity, leverage, asset managenent, and profitability. Incluled in them ratios in Tables 3-1 and 3-2 is fixed asset turnover which is l2 discussed in greater detail in Chapter 5. Another possible ratio for measuring misvalued assets, Tobin's q, was considered but not included. Because of its wide acceptance, the decision not to use that ratio should be explained. To begin, valuation disequilibriuns are illogical to financial theorists who believe the market pricing mechanisn should restore an equilibriun to market values and replacanent values. 'lhere are many reasons for a misvaluation of physical assets ranging fron the obvious potential of obsolescence to the less obvious discount rate used to value the increnental cash flows of that asset by a host of potential acquirers possessing varying risk levels, to the range of values from going concern values to liquidating values. A theorist will contend the above three reasons ought to apply to equity share values as well, but will intuitively concede a misvaluation is more likely to exist in the appraisal of a partially depreciated physical asset than for an equity share actively traded in a secondary auction market. Such a potential misvaluation introduces the availability of risk adjusted excess returns to the arbitraguer. James Tobin developed a ratio to measure the discremncy between market values and reproduction values of assets which is now referred to as the q ratio. 'ihe mnerator of his ratio is the market valuation, the prevailing market price for exchanging existing assets. His denaninator is the replacement or reproduction cost, the market price for newly produced assets.20 Tobin believed that disequilibriuns existed for more than brief time periods for two reasons: 1. in exanples of improvenents on real property a time lag exists because of construction time, and 2. 13 valuations of existing assets will be more volatile than for the price of 21 However, ultimately the nunerator and denoninator reproductions. will be brought into equilibriun. Indeed, a market value greater than replacenent value provides an incentive to create more of the asset in pursuit of an economic profit which will persist until either market values fall, reproduction costs rise, or both. The significance of q to the merger movenent is not clear because its enpirical test are inconclusive, in spite of the contentions of its advocates. 'mroughout the 19605, the ratio was greater than one, based on Tobin and Brainard's original enpirical stuiies.22 Q rose from 2.21 in 1960 to 2.54 in 1968, dropped to 2.12 in 1969, and plunged to 0.97 in 1974. Q levels higher than one are expected to stimulate investment and in response, the 19605 are now characterized as the decade of conglonerate mergers. Tobin attributed the drop in q from 1973 to 1974 as being due to a spectacular rise in the discount rate applied to earnings brought about by tight anti-inflationary monetary policies rather than to declines in earnings.23 'ihe drop in the value of q also coincided with the end of the great merger era. Q fell to .8 in 1974-75 and according to one researcher is now at .73 in spite of the record levels of merger activity.24 If a high q is expected to stimulate investment and produces record levels of mergers, ought not we to expect an absence of mergers if q is at levels below 1, given the disincentive to invest? According to Ciccolo, q levels less than one, accanpanied by low prices of equities, make it cheaper for firms to acquire other firm, lu invest in treasury bills, or increase cash dividends rather than make new capital invesirnents.25 He contends it is the low level of q currently that accounts for the record merger activity which began in the latter half of the 197%. Ciccolo's theory does not explain the high q levels associated with the merger experience of the 19605, nor does he define low stock prices or when they cease being "low." Other enpirical studies of q produce conflicting results. Von Furstenberg, Malkiel,ani Watson [127] concluded q was a powerful influence on levels of investment. Fbwever, testing for q at the firm level, rather than in the aggregate, Chappel and Cheng produced contradictory results, generally as a function of the industry in which a canpamr functioned.26 'ihere also appears to be a measurement problem in quantifying q. Ciccolo calculated q to be 1.65 in 1965,27 well below the 2.5 calculated by Tobin.28 At the sane time, the Council of Econanic Advisers which also calculates q, determined its level to be 1.25.29 In 1974, Tobin calculated q to be 0.97,30 Ciccolo calculated it to be 0.8,31 and the Council of Fconanic Advisers determined q to be 0.663.32 Because Ciccolo contends that at any time span q levels vary from firm to firm, it would seen that care must be taken in selecting a "repeaentative" sanple. Furthermore, the potential for misvaluation exists in spite of sample selection. Because Tobin and Brainard used a set of valuation assunptions, those assumptions have been followed in subsequent tests, doubtlessly to pranote "canparability." Tobin's q ratio nunerator, in alpirical tests, is not the market value of assets, it is the market 15 value of the firm's cannon stock, preferred stock and long term debt. Ironically, the first step in the testing process to measure disequilibrium of asset values and stock values is to assune that they are in equilibriun. It is difficult to test for misvalmtions by presuning there are none. Because the available data bases do not provide market values for bonds and preferred stocks, their market values must be estimated. Canpanies are assuned to have Pea twenty year maturity long term debt (Chappel and Cheng assumed twenty years, but matched yields according to ratings classes),33 and their preferred stock is valued at the year and Standard and Poor index of preferred stock yield, regardless of the firm's risk level.34 Those estimates do not seen critical however, when compared to the potential errors from estimations used in the denaninator. ’I'he denaninator, replacenent cost, " . . . is the sum of the book values of canmon stock, preferred stock, and long term debt, connected by a cannon annual index of the ratio of replacement cost to book value."35 'Ihe replacement cost of assets is an attempt to adjust for depreciable assets at the rate of five percent per year as opposed to accounting depreciation. It is also to revalue inventories at replacement cost and adjust for inflation using the price deflator for the fixed investment canponent of GNP. Strangely, the category "other assets" is left at book value. Unfortunately, "other assets" incluies marry of the potential misvaluations, especially land and intangible assets.36 Perhaps most puzzling is Ciccolo' s contention that individual firms have varying q ratios}.7 That implies varying degrees of disequilibriun at the firm level, and more specifically that those firms b0. M , 16 are not being valued at the correct discount rate. Both investment professionals and the acadenic community must be interested in his perceptions of the correct discount rates for various firms. To conclude, intuitively the prospect of some assets beirg misvalued by potential acquirers are more probable than for other assets. Bit anpirical tests to date do not clearly demonstrate that entire firms are being valued incorrectly given their existing managenent and current econanic states of nature. c. Accountirg Treatment of Mergers The accounting treatment of mergers, which changed in the 1970's has probably lost its presumed sign.ificance.38r3§9 A stuiy conducted by Hong, Kaplan and Mandelker indicates the pooling-of- interest method of accounting for mergers did not lead to abnormal stock returns.40 Mthemore, they contend that the efficient capital market should be able to see through the particular accounting convention used to describe amerger and respond to the "econanies of the merger, not its accounting description."41 In a separate stuiy, Phndelker found no evidence of accounting treaiment of mergers influencing the profitability of a mergerfl'2 Nevertheless, misconceptions persist. Ferguson and Pbfidn's recent article disregarded pro-merger price appreciation of target firms and the presence of negative risk adjusted excess returns accruing to acquirers in the post merger period, contending that existing accounting conventions for depreciation encouraged mergers.43 d. Price-Earning Ratios Vergers occurring in the 19605 were often "justified" by the expectation that a parent firm's price-earnings (p/e) ratio may 17 remain unchanged after it acquired a firm with a lower p/ e, and presuned lower growth prospects. Such an acquisition, in theory, should depress the price-earnings ratio of the acquiring firm. 'Jhe new price—earnings ratio should reflect this change in outlook for the growth of the canbined firm. Aside fran the more obvious defects in a price-earnings analysis (vis—a—vis the quality of earnings], it is the value of the canbined firm, not its earnings, which is the relevant test. *************** Some acquisitions have less econanic suitability than others. It is those which are discussed next. 4. Moments Merger Effects Conglanerate mergers are defined as those mergers which lack any of the operational, market-share, or financial advantages previously discussed. In the absence of those advantages, any two firms whose returns over time are less than perfectly positively correlated will benefit fran diversification creating a superior risk adjusted investment due to the redmtion of the costs of bankruptcy. Levy and firnat observe: . . . diversification can be expected to produce a true econanic gain owing to the fact that the canbination of the financial resources of the two firms making up the merger reduces lenders' risk while canbining each of the individual shares (fl the two companies in investors’ portfolios does not. Most of the other reasons for conglomerate mergers are categorized as operating, managenent, or financial effects which are not exclusive to conglanerate mergers. Alberta, in illustrating the reduction of risk, erroneously concluied investors could diversify their own portfolios. However, he am 3 18 [ failed to consider bankruptcy costs.45 ‘ Haley and Schall concede that once bankruptcy costs are considered, " . . . there may be benefits from reducing financial distress costs as a consequence of the mergers.”6 Rubinstein states: Bankruptcy penalties, . . . , create an incentive to merge since mergers st invariably diminish the probability of bankruptcy. Synergistic benefits could clearly cause the same project to have diffefient marginal dollar returns and costs to different firms. levy and Sarnat suggest: . . . mergers may create financial advantages. For exanple, large firms have better access to the capital markets and also enjoy significant cost savings when securing their financial needs. Iogue and Naert advocate conglomerate mergers not only for the previously mentioned reasons but also because of an extension of the diversification argunent, called the "resource allocation and resource utilization synergflfio Baugen and Iangetieg, in discussing synergy, observe that it: . . . may result because the merger makes possible entry into new product lines which change the level, stability and cyclical nature of the firm's profitability. Vertical canbination may reduce the risk of fluctuations in the price and availability of raw materials. It is possible that managanent of the acquired firm is replaced by individuals who are more aggressive in nature. Merger may raise the profitability of a depressed firm in poor financial coalition and significantly reduce the risk of bankruptcy. Fbr the relatively snall firm, it opens new sources of capital and it may also reduce the possibility of insolvency due to an unfavorable liquidity position. It may also significantly affect the volatility of the market value of their common stock. In any case . . . these factors should manifest thanselves in a change in the distribution of rates of return to stockholders of the merged firm. a. Foreig Aguisitions Another motive for mergers which might be categorized in a l9 conglanerate context is an extension of the risk reduction argunent for diversification; the acquisition of foreign based assets to reduce further the systematic risk in a portfolio [24,36,EQ,115,122]. Such redmtion of systenatic risk is due to the less than perfect positive correlation of the respective asset returns. Aside from diversi- fication benefits, there are additional risk reducing factors explaining this activity in the United States. Those factors incluie political instability and foreign exchange. "There exists a desire to shelter capital by moving it into the canparative safety of the United States.”2 What is perceived as an increase in socialian in Eirope53 and in Canada54 has made the United States appear to be one of the last bastions of a capitalist-oriented free enterprise system.55 Regarding foreign exchange: Foreign buyers have special reasons of their own for playing the takeover game. With both the dollar and the stock market on the mat, U. S. canpanies look enchanti%ly cheap, even though their earnings are also in dollars. Carberry canmented on the relative "cheapless" of U. S. corporations [40]. Regarding Real Estate Invesiment Trusts: In Elrope there aren't as many properties available for investment; it takes longer to arrange financing, and most deals are done with at least 50% cash. An added allure for foreigners is the low value of the dollar relative to foreign currencies and the cgmparative security of investments in the United States. Rout also comments on foreign acquisitions of United States canranies: 'Ihe foreigners appetites for U. S. concerns have been whetted during the last two years by a variety of coniitims, ranging from the weak U. S. dollar . . . 'Ihe foreigners are cashing in on a canbination of cheap canpanies and cheap dollars. . . . with the weak dollar has meant the U. S. canpanies are undervalued absolutelg and even more so given the currencies of the acquirers.l5 20 Fran an untitled article in a European publication came the following qwtation: " . . . movenents in exchange rates and recent rates of inflation have made the United States again a relatively low cost producing area . . . "59 *************** D. Literature Review — Manfirial Therm The Managenent Theory of Mergers led Weller to explain abnormally low returns of firms during the post-merger period canpared to the pro-merger period. He sugests that corporate managenent may be at cross purposes with the broad goals of the corporation in that while a corporation seeks maximization of the firm's value, managers often are canpensated for their ability to produce asset expansion. Managerial salaries, bonuses, stock options, and pranotions all tend to be more closely related to the size or changes in size of the firm than to its profits.60 In one observation of mergers policy within A. H. Robbins, the acquisitions staff was split into teens. The head of one team wanted to find the acquisition so he could put another picture on his office wall to accanpany pictures of other acquisitions for which he was responsible, according to a critic on one of the other acquisition teens.61 Mueller also contends that snaller growth oriented firms have higher marginal rates of return than do more mature firms.62 A similar statement can be made about their marginal cost of capital. Furthermore, the invesiment opportunities of the mature firm, within its traditional business activities, are more restricted. Because of that, the schedule of marginal rates of return on invesiments is likely to 21 intersect well within the horizontal segment of its marginal cost—of- capital function. If Mueller's contentions are correct, the results would have enormous ramifications in merger theory and in the valuation of acquisitions. His article produced several rebuttals and observations [84,3,73,86] as well as his subsequent reply [102]. Mueller's argunent that mature firms have lower costs of capital drew criticisn fran Copeland and Weston: If the managers were making investment decisions using an investment hurdle rate below a market equilibriun rate and therefore below the alternative returns to stockholders, stockholders would shift their investment to firms offering higher rates of return. Basic capital market forces would not permit differe firms to follow a 'two-tier' investment hurdle rate policy. The reconciliation of these views is reasonably simple. Mueller, in discussing conglomerates, seems to have missed the correct rationale for his own argunent. Acquiring firms do not use lower discount rates in order to maximize growth rather than shareholder wealth. As Iogue and Naert observed: . . . a firm . . . (holding a group of diversified assets with significant overall variance reducing covariance effects) will be able to establish a broader clientele of investors and ézzius because of the greater clientele, sell at a higher price. . . . we would rather argue that a lower discount rate is us because of managenent's expectation of synergistic effects. 5 However, it is Wizeller's first contention-that firms maximize growth, not shareholder wealth maximi zation—that draws the most criticism. Iewellen and Huntsnan's study of fifty of the top ninety-four canpanies in the Fortune 500, from 1942—1963, regressed managerial canpensation on profits and sales. then to avoid debate over whether 22 profits maximization ms the same as stockholder wealth maximization, they ran a second regression replacing profits with market value of equity. In both instances, the regressions produced high coefficients of determination. The coefficient of sales was insignificant in both regressions, and coefficients of both profits and market value of equity were large in their respective regressions.66 Haley and Schall devoted an entire chapter to the concept that firm objectives, in imperfect markets, might produce coalitions where firm—value maximization is inconsistent with shareholder-wealth maximization. The most likely of the two causes for divergence exists if a firm adopts investments which change the risk of the firm's outstanding bonds.67 If management pursues policies that maximize the total value of the firm's securities, under sane circunstances those policies may result in lower values for the firmég shares, but higher values for the firm's debt [bonds]. rihe second cause for a divergence is less likely. Ibre, the firm issues new bonds which are not of a lower priority than the old bonds. It ignores corporate taxes, relies heavily upon perfect capital markets, and assunes that the firm's value will not change, regardless of its debt-equity ratio.59 Regarding managerial canpensation, Cort contends, " . . . merge frequencies vary greatly anong industries [and are] highly concentrated in some industries.”0 He continues: . . . if mergers are a consequence of the personal ambitions of managers to manage large firms, why is it, then, unless anbitious men tend to exist in certain industries, that you have oonceptraticns of merger activity within certain industries? 1 Still the case that firms maximize shareholder wealth is not 23 universally clear, according to Conn and Nielsen;72 as well as others. Reid, in his book on mergers, discusses several stuiies which contend otherwise:73 Those studies reviewed include Eaunol's stuiy which states: Indeed, in talldng to business executives one may easily cane to believe that the growt of the firm is the main preoccupation of top managenent. . . . managenent's goal may well be to max ize 'sales' [total revenue] subject to a profit constraint. A subsequent test by McGuire, et. al., stlxiied correlations between executive incanes, sales, and profits of 45 of the largest 100 industrial corporations from 1953-1959. 'Ihe results indicated: . . the evidence presented would seen to support the likelihood that there is a valid relationship between sales and execligive incanes but not between profits and executive incomes. In another study, Roberts concluded the relationship between sales and executive canpensation appeared to be stronger than the relationship between canpensation and profits?7 Patton studied 420 canpanies in the period 1953-1964 and determined that canpany size was the chief determinant of top executive pay.78 Additionally: Since sales growth is such an important variable in determining top managenent incane, there is a basis for conflict between the personal intenfgsts of top managenent and the interests of shareholders." Wanna has created such a scenario: Generally speaking, managers' incentives and interests coincide with their shareholders in every particular except one: They have no incentives as managers to keep managenent services for the company at the lowest possible price. To the extent that the sane individuals are also shareholders, their motivation will reflect a conflict. Even if the market for corporate control is working perfectly, so long as the cost to the corporation of the incunbent manager's inefficiency is below the cost to an outsider of taking over control, the 2L! insiders will renain secure in the positions with high salaries. This may furnish sane proof for thifiwtion that executive canpensation is a function of size. Dean and Snith are very critical of the Baunol and the McGuire, Chin and Elbing studies. Regarding Baunol, they criticize his "uncritical acceptance" of executive interviews and their public statenents that "growth has a new and independent status."81 Dean and Snith assert that "in a time that values growth, annual reports and other corporate utterances will stress anything that can be used to show that the firm is in progressive alliance with the trend of the times."82 They also criticized the McGuire, Chiu, and Elbing stuiy addressing the lack of standard definitions of managenent and compensation to mean the same thing for different size and industry groups.85 Also: The managenent job is in part the efficient administration of a collection of assets; and the profitability of these assets, especially in the short run, will usually be determined far more by externals thaéhr by the special contributions of a current managenent." Much of the preceding was based on manager activities in the 19505 and 19605. Fhrbar, in what may be indicative of different circunstances, discusses merger activity in the 19705. He indicates shareholders have been suing directors for neglecting fiduciary duties.85 Gerber's board is being sued by shareholders who believe they should have been the ones to accept or reject Anderson Clayton's offer last year. Courts historically have been hesitant to second—guess a board of directors, but Gerber's shareholders have a chance of winning their suit. The board spurred a friendly feeler fron Unilever while it was fighting Anderson Clayton; the directors' motives seemed to be to keep the company independe rather than get the best possible deal for shareholders. Similarly, 25 Universal Leaf is being sued for thwarting Congoleum's offer, and Marshall Field is being sued over its successful defense of Carter Hawley Hale's takeover attempt. However the suits are decided, the prospect of having to answer shareholders in court has alrgfidy begun to influence the behavior of outside directors. Such legal actions reinforce wfarme's contention that mergers or a threat of takeover by more efficient management acts as an incentive for inefficient managers.88 *************** E. Literature Review — Shareholder Returns Firms are acquired on the theoretical grounds of a "fit." The question is whether or not the acquisition produced the desired synergistic effect. Dodd and Hiback assert: The effect of mergers upon the value of the firm has been a contentious issue in the literature and empirical investigations have presented conflicting results. Many of 122?? 52:33: ifenefiieifcgfiiiiififiirmf§f$%°%is and What stuiies of post-merger returns behavior of the acquiring firm suggest that returns are normal or less than normal in the post-merger period and any gains accrue to shareholders of the acquired firms. Melker's study is cited here because it is one of the more recent stuiies (1974), and uses the two factor market model [87]. He concluies that the acquiring firm' s monthly returns are normal in the post-merger period and shareholders earn abnormal returns of approximately 14% on the average in the seven months preceding the merger.90 Dodd and Ruback contend that andelker did not consider what may be an important consideration in measuring any potential abnormal 26 returns to stockholders of acquiring firms. Mandelker reports that shareholders of acquired firms earn abnormal positive returns over the seven months before the merger month. If the mergers in his sample are preceded on average by a tender offer or similar announcement, the prenerger gains could reflect the market reaction to the earlier release of this information. Using tender offer dates, Dodd and Ruback discovered: . . in the month of the announcement, target firm stockholders earn large and significant abn8§mal returns of 20. 58 percent for successful offers. . . . The paper also contains the first enpirical assessment of the market reaction to unsuccessful takeover attanpts. The stockholders of bidding firms which initiate unsuccessful tender offers neither gain nor lose—-they earn normal returns in the offer period. Unsuccessful target firms, however, earn large significant positive abnormal returns of 18.96 percent in the month the offer is announced. Furthermore, the price change is permanent since they earn normal returns for five years after the offer.93 Mandelker does not indicate what percent of his sample experienced prior tender offers, but the potential for a bias exists. There probably are many more tender offers now than there were prior to Marflelker's study. According to Ehrbar, in his discussion of recent characteristics of mergers: The current takeover wave got started in 1974 [the year Walker's dissertation was published], and has been building ever since. More and more of the takeovers sea to be hostile, i.e. , opposed by the target's management. Eirbar asserts that the targets are a lot larger in asset size than they used to be 95 and "Most important the bidders have been paying 27 higher praniuns than ever."96 Historically, according to Benjanin Graham, tender offers have been made at prices averaging around 20—50% above the market value of the target stock prices.97 Nerjos, in her stuiy (1977), found premiuns to be 40-50%.98 Recently the premiums have been averaging more than 60%, and the contested deals have been even hotter. The average premiun in the ten $100 million-plus contests last year was more than 80%. In a few ases the raiders paid more than double the market value.98 How can there be such a disparity between existing prices and either tender offer prices, or merger prices? Is there any evidence in the literature indicating that those premiuns were warranted? Most stuiies conclude that the gains, if any, generally accrue to the shareholders of the acquired firm. The existence of positive postnerger gains accruing to shareholders of acquiring firms is less certain. Conn and Nielsen, in an enpirical stuiy of an earlier model by Iarson ani Gonedes (Ir-G) [77] found a significant nunber of mergers resulted in losses to both acquirer and acquired firms.100 However, the wealth loss ms much greater for acquiring firms than acquired . "Rarely did the acquiring firm's stockholders gain while the acquired firm‘s stockholders lost."101 Regarding the interests of the shareholders, " . . . at least 40% of the mergers [in their study] do not conform to the rationality assunption that the bargaining process is constrained by each firm maintaining at least its stockholders' wealth status in the period of the merger."102 One flaw acknowledged by the authors in the study is that the L-G model made no provision for the possible change in the risk-return profile of the merger participants.103 AS the authors contend, "If a merger results in reduction of systematic risk that is unobtainable for existing stockholders . . . their risk return position T" 28 may actually improve even if return declines.104 Dodd [1976], in a study of Australian equities, found shareholders of canpanies receiving takeover offers benefited whether or not the acquisition was completedf earnirrespective (185 the outcome, [those] shareholders gains. . . . 0n the other hand, shareholders of acquiring firms suffered significant losses after takeovers. It appears that any gains arising from the merger-werewon b66the acquired firms at the expense of the acquiring firms. In a more recent study of NYSE firms in the 1970s, Dodd (1980) found results similar to those of his Australian study. Here the acquired firm earns returns of 13%, and the non-acquired firm earns almost 11%, even though their managenent vetoed the proposed takeover. If the potential acquirer called off the merger, prices returned to previous levels. Finally, losses of 7% accrued to stockholders of successful bidders in the post—merger period.107 Lev and Manialker (IN), using a paired canparison sanple and annual returns, concluded (1) there is no evidence of risk reduction fron mergers and (2) the acquisition produced a decrease in the growth rate in the post—merger period, relative to non-merging firms, which he referred to as a "digestion effect."108 Other results in the study indicated there were no tax effects, and no evidence of accounting treatment of mergers influencing the profitability of merger. Instead the accounting treatments tended to *Emis paper also provides a fifty year summary of merger stuiies in the United States beginning with Dewing‘s stuiy. Dewing, Arthur S., "A Statistical Test of the Success of Cmaolidaticns." Quarterly Journal of Economics 36 (1921): 84-121. 29 Imderstate the profitability of mergers.109 Because of the use of annual returns, their study " . . . did not investigate short run effects."110 Both Reid (1975) and Ibneycutt criticized the L"! stuiy. Reid because, "426 of the non-merger' s [control group] had as many or more mergers . . . than the acquiring firms.111 Honeycutt argues that an acquisition would change the primary industry classification of the acquiring firm, while the control firm would not change, reducing the value of a paired canparison.112 In another study, Reid found that companies growing internally grew at a rate of 601% versus 307% for canpanies actively involved in mergers during the period 1951—1961. His study involved 478 of the nation's largest oorporations.”3 He attributed this finding to the substantial preniuns over market value paid for assets acquired.114 Halpern concluied, in a study of mergers between large and snall firms, that adjusted gains were positive to both groups and divided eveniy.“5 His study of '78 mergers in the period 1950-1965 did not include firms actively acquiring other firms, nor did he make any attenpt to separate buyers fron sellers. . . . this distinction [separating buyers from sellers] is arbitrary and has no econanic justification. Since we do '1‘? hfi‘iii‘éfifiia’r‘i it?iiiirt’iiff’gexfgé’fii‘““521 *3 13°53 1% We He also disregarded diversification argunents, citing investor diversification and attributed the positive gains to good "fits."1"'7 Haugen and Iangetieg stuiied 59 mergers in the period 1951-1958, using a 72 month time series and concluied: . . . a merger fails to produce economically significant changes in the distribution of rates of return to the stockholder. Orr attention centers on the risk attributes 30 of the distribution, and we do not address dollar benefits of canbination which are capitalized in the stock price with the armouncflignt and subsequent consunmation of the combination. Hogarty studying 43 mergers in the period 1953-1964 were " . . . judged unsuccessful" to the acquirer using annual returns.119 But, a few " . . . obtain very large returns, and the prospect of these large returns tempts other firms to engage in merger activity."120 In Iangetieg' s couprehensive three factor model (a zero beta with an industry factor and a matched non—merging control group) using monthly data seventy two months before and after amerger of 149 mergers, he observed returns of 12% to the acquired stockholders over the interval 6 months to 1 month prior to amerger. These results replicate Mandelker's study [87]. Regarding shareholders of acquiring firms, Iangetieg found positive pre-merger returns: However, the gain is clearly too small to conclude that enhancanents of stockholder welfare is the sole motive for merger. . . . perhaps another motive . . . managerial welfare 1 gmay have been the instrunental cause of the merger. (he enpirical study supports the managerial motive. The explanation is the difference in risk perception of managers and stockholders. Stockholders can diversify asset portfolios, but managers do not have portfolios of enployers. Managers may acquire firms not to enhance profits but rather to make the firm less risky, making jobs more stable.122 Nblicher and Fhrter found that prices of acquiring canpanies are "bid-up” before rather than after merger benefits, especially when the acquired canpany was more than 1/2 the size of the acquiring company, [measured by total assets]."123 r 31 Nielsen and Melicher found no support for " . . . instantaneous or real financial synergy."124 When financial gains were obtained, it occurred in instances where acquiring firms were able to pay below prmiuns for their acquisitions.”5 Bradley's stuiy of one-hundred sixty one successful tender offers produced " . . . conpelling evidence for a. synergy theory of tender offers."126 Perhaps Bradley's results are contradicted though by the initial experiences of tendering stockholders fron thirty firms which experienced sizeable share price reductions in the post—tender period 1969—1970.127 *************** F. Conclusion The evidence generally indicates that market price appreciation of merged firms takes place seven to thirty months prior to the event. The gains going primarily to the acquired firms suggests little support for the monopoly theories since there was rarely evidence that both parties profited. (he recent article contends that as many as seventy percent of all mergers are unsuccessful [110]. Sane evidence exists to support the managerial theory, that there is a. cmflict between shareholders and managenent. Weston and Rice [130] anong others, conclude: The inefficient utilization of econanic resources by the prior managenent leads to their being acquired by firms with a. prior record of above average performance. Hence the evidence leans in the dirfigion of efficiency and/ or synergy as the explanation . . . (he survey of one Imndred seventy five chief financial officers involved in 1978 mergers iniicated their perception was the horizontal mergers were more successful than vertical or conglomerate mergers.129 32 The fact that the acquisitions have had "subnormal" performance previous to the merger coupled with the efficiency explanation provides the incentive to determine that such subpar performance will be reflected in the firm's financial statements.130 To sunnarize this chapter, it was necessary to discuss the theories of mergers as motives appearing in the literature, as well as other motives advanced by both arbitrageurs and by mergers staffs. By understanding the motives for mergers, it may becane possible to predict then. If firms are acquired because of their financial characteristics, such characteristics should be reflected in the financial statenents of the acquired firm. The purpose of this study is to generate three models which use financial ratios to predict mergers. In the next chapter, various ratios are examined which purportedly measure incentives for mergers and hence provide predictive content. Chapter II Footnotes See: "Asset Redeployment: Everything Is For Sale Now," Business Week, 24 August 1%1, p. 71, for a discussion of incorrect future discount rate to be used on forecasted future cash inflows. See: William M. (hrley, "Airline Service Reakdown Persists Iong After Pan Am, National Merge," Wall Street Journal, 10 March 1981, p. 25. "During one November week, 154,000 calls weren't answered. 'We'll never know how mmh revenue we lost.‘ says William Waltrip, executive vice president of Pan m." "In buying National, Pan Am got four M105 it didn't need, and hasn't been able to sell then because ofaglut of used aircraft on the market. Pan Am also has a brand new $45 million 11310 sitting on the ground at the NcDonnell Douglas plant near Ios Angeles. The plane, which isn't needed now, had been ordered by National." Also, see: Thonas Petzinger, "To Win a Bidding War Doesn't Ensure Slccess of Merged Companies." Wall Street Journal, 1 Septenber 1981, pp. 1, 12. J. R'ed Weston and Eihard 1". Rice, "Discussion," Journal of Finance 31 (May. 1976): 745. —— Ibid. W. W. Alberta and J. E. Segall The Co rate Var r (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, mesh—W . German i’hndelker, "Risk and Return: The case of the Merging Firm," Journal of Financial Economics 1 (Decenber, 1974): 305. Thanas E. Copeland and J. Red Weston, Financial Theo and Comrate Polig (Menlo Park: Addison Wesley, 1W9): :23. Wilbur G. Iewellm, "A Pure Financial Rationale for the Conglanerate Morgen: Journal of Finance 26 (May, 1971): 522. Copeland and Weston, p. 423. Charles W. Eloy and Iawrence D. Schall, The Theom of Financial 33 16. 17. 18. 311 Decisions, 21d ed. (New York: McGraw Hill Book Company, 1979): 447. Henry G. Mamas, "Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control," Journal of Political Econggx 73 (April, 1965): 110. Ibid, p. 111. Ibid. Ibid, p. 113. John Lintner, "Expectations, Nbrgers and Ehuilibriun in Purely Cgfititixg. Securities Markets," American Economic Review 61 (Why, George Finches and Kent A. Mingo, "A Multivariate Analysis of Industrial Bond Ratings," Journal of Finance 28 (March, 1973): Iewellen, "A Pure Financial Rationale," p. 522. Copeland and Weston, p. 426. Ihley and Schall, p. 446. Donald Iee Stevens, "A Miltivariate Analysis of Financial Characteristics of Acquired Firms in Industrial 1"Iergers" (Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State University, 1972), p. 19. Janes Tobin and Willian C. Brainard, "Asset Markets and the Cost of Capital, " Cowles Foundation Paper No. 440 (New Haven: Cowles Founiation for Research in Econanics at Yale University, 1977): 235. Ibid, pp. 236—237. Ibid. pp- 254-255- Ibid, p. 262. Seymour flicker, "'Ihe Q—Ratio: Fuel for the Merger Fania," Business Wed:, 24 August 1981, p. 30. Ibid. Enry W. mappell, Jr. and David C. Cheng, "E: T‘ctations, 'Ibbin's q and Investment: A Note," Journal of Finance 37 ,1982): 231. kicker, p. 30. Tobin and Brainand, p. 254. Adan l’eyerson, "Merger Mania and the High Takeover Premiuns," W_all Street Journal, 20 July 1981, p. 14 ibbin and Brainard, p. 254. 41 . 42. 43- 45- 47. 35 Zucker, p. 30. beerson, p. 14. Chappell and Cheng, p. 232. Tobin and Brainard, p. 249. Ibid. Snappell and Cheng, p. 233. Zuclner, p. 30. Iewellen among others believed some investors were deceived by misvaluations of mergers in the 19603. See Iewellen, pp. 522-523. Elier, et a1, believe that more conservative accounting resulting fran the passage of APB 16 and 17, coupled with other factors reduced merger activity but fostered more soundly conceived mergers. See: H. Kent Baker, Thanas 0. Miller, and Brian J. Ransparger, "An Inside Iook)at Corporate Mergers and Acquisitions," MSU Topics 29 (Winter, 1%1 : 49. Bai Hang, Ibbert S. Vaplan, and Gershon Mandellner, "Pooling vs. Purchase: The Effects of Accounting for Mergers on Stock Prices," The Accountipg Review 53 (Janmry, 1978): 44. Ibid, p. 31. Mandelker, pp. 307, 330. Robert Ferguson and Phillip Rafldn, "Pulling Ihbbits Oit of I-hts in the Oil Easiness - and Elsewhere," inancial 11mm Journal 38 (Wareh— April, 1%2): 25- Beim levy and Marshall Sarnatt, "Diversification, Portfolio Analysis and the Uneasy Case for Conglanerate Mergers," Journal o_f Finance 25 (Septanber, 19170): 801. — --- Alberta and Segall, pp. 262-272. lhley and Szhall, p. 446. Mark E. Rubinstein, A Mean-Variance S thesis of Co rate Financial Theo . ed. SEE C. MyTers, Raern Develo ents in Comrafi financial Theory (New York: Praeger fiblisfiers, 1976), p. 47. Ibid, p. 51. Ievy and arnatt, "Diversification, Portfolio Analysis," p. m1. 50. 51. 52. 53. 54. 55. 56. 57. 59. 60. 61. 62. 63. 64. 66. 67. 68. 70. 36 Dennis E. Iogue and Pnillippe A. T‘aert, "A 'I‘heory of Conglomerate "ergers: Comment and Iktension," Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 (November, 1970): 665-666. Robert A. Haugen and Terrence C. Iangetieg, "An Vmpirical 'f‘est for synergism in T-"erger," Journal of Finance 30 (September, 1975): 1004. Iawrence Rout, "Ewing American: Weak Dollar, Stocks Spur Foreigners to Seek Acquisitions In The United States," Wall Street Journal 21 August 1979, p. 1. "'Ihe Great Takeover Pings," Pusiness Week, 14 November 1977: 1'78- 179. "A Financial T’mpire In The Taking," Business Week, 91"arch 1991: 87. "Market Commentary: T'ergers and Acquisitions - How To Buy An American Company," Furomoney, November, 1976, p. 141. A. F. Ehrbar, "Corporate Takeovers Are Here to Stay," Fortune, 8 “Kay 1978: 91 . James Carberry, "P.”any REITs Stage Comeback, Aided Py An Attraction of Foreign Investors," Wall Street Journal, 6 August 1979, p. 6. Rout, p. 1. "I‘~'arket Commentary," Furomoney, p. 141. Dennis C. Mueller, "A Theory of Conglomerate Vergers," Quarterly Journal of Economics 83 (November, 1969): 644. Victor Zonana, "Planning A Plant: How A. H. Robins Co. Wade Decision to Puild a Chemical Facility," Wall Street Journal, 22 October 1975, p. 1. 1‘711eller, pp. 646-647. Copeland and Weston, p. 429. Iogue and I’aert, p. 664. 65. Ibid, p. 665. Wilbur G. Iewellen and Elaine Huntsman, "Vanagerial Pay and Corporate figfomance," American Economic Review 60 (September, 1970): 711- Paley and Schall, p. 478. Ibid, p. 482. 69. Ibid, p. 478. Michael Cort, "An Phonemic Disturbance Theory Of T’ergers," Ellarterly Journal of Economics ‘35 November, 1969): 625. 71 . 72. 74. 75. 76. (micago: University of Chicago Press, 1966): 8. 37 Ibid. R. L. Conn and J. P. Nielsen, "An Empirical Test of the Iarson-Gonedes Exchange Ratio Determination Model," Journal of Finance 32 (June, 1977): 754-756. Samuel Richardson Reid, “-iergersLVanagers, and the Economy (New York: ichraw-Hill Book Campanyf1968): 135. William J. Baunol, "01 the Theory of the I‘x nsion of the Firm," American Economic Review 52 (December, 1962 : 1078. Ibid , p. 1085. Joseph W. P’bGuire, John S. Y. Chiu, and Alvas O. Elbing, "Executive Incomes, Sales, ani Profits," American Economic Review 52 (September, 1962): 760. D. R. Roberts, Executive Compensation (New York: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1959). Arch Patton, "Deterioration In To Ececutive Pay," Harvard Business Review 43 (November-December, 1975 : 106. Ibid, p. 113. Henry G. Nanne, "l‘ergers and the Market for Corporate Control," Journal of Political Economy 73 ( April, 1965): 117- Joel Dean and Winfield Smith, The Relationships Between Profitability and Size, ed. W. W. Alberts and J. E. Segall, rI‘he Corporate Verger Ibid. Ibid, p. 7. Ibid. A. F. Ihrbar, "Corporate Takeovers Are Here to Stay," Fortune, 8 T‘Tay 1978, p. 96. Ibid. Ibid. I"WIDE, p. 113. Rater Dodd and Richard Ruback, "Tender Offers and Stocldmolder Returns, An Enpirical Analysis," Journal of Financial Economics 5 (December, 19'77): 351 . Valflelker, p. 303. 91 . 92. 93- 94. 95- 96. 97. 98. 99. 100. 101. 102. 103. 104. 105. 1%. 107. 1%. 109. 110. 111. 112. 113. 38 Dodd and Ruback, P. 352. Ibid. Ibid. Emrbar, p. 91. Ibid. Also, while there are not nearly as many mergers created in the 1970s, the dollar value of the latter are almost equal to that of the former. See "’Ihe Great Takeover Binge," p. 176. Fhrbar, p. 91. Ibid. Anna Pbrjos, "Takeover Targets," Parrons, 15 Way 1978, p. 14. Ihrbar, p. 91. Conn and Nielsen, pp. 755-756. Ibid, p. 755. Ibid, p. 754. Ibid, p. 758. Ibid. Rater Dodd, "Company Takeovers and the Australian Equity i’arket," Australian Journal of Management 1 (October, 1976): 24. Ibid. Idem, "P“erger Proposals, Vanagement Discretion, and Stockholder Wealth," Journal 2f Financial Economics 8 (T-’Tarch, 1980): 105. Baruch Lev and Gershon thdelker, "The Nicroeconomic Consequences of Corporate "ergers," Journal of Busine$ 45 (January, 1972): 97. Ibid, p. 102. Ibid, p. 103. Samuel Richardson Reid, "'Ihe F-“icroeconamic Consequences of Corporate Mer‘gers: Comment," Journal of Business 48 (April, 1975): 280- T. Crawford Honeycutt, "The I‘icroeconomic Consequences of Corporate Mergers: A Comment," Journal of Business 48 (April, 1975): 267° "Growing From Within Way Pay Off 1Register," Business Week, 17 Saptenber, 1966, p. 44. 114. 115. 122. 125. 124. 125. 126. 127. 128. 129. 130. 39 Ibid, p. 46. Paul J. Halpern, "Empirical Istimates of the Amount and Distribution Gains to Companies in '"ergers," Journal of Business 46 (October 1973): 570. Ibid, p. 557. Ibid, p. 573. Haugen and Iangetieg, p. 1003. Thomas F. Hogarty, "(me Profitability of Corporate Tv'ergers," Journal of Business 43 (July, 1970): 322. "““" Economics 6 (December, 1978): 382. Ibid, p. 326. Terence Iangetieg, "An Application of a Three-Ractor Performance Index to Yeasure Stockholder Gains From 1'erger," Journal of Financial Yakov Amihud and Baruch Iev, "Risk Reduction as a Vanagerial Motive for Conglomerate P’ergers," The Bell Journal of Economics 12 (Autumn, 1981 : 606. Ronald W. '"elicher and Thomas R. Harter, "Abstract: Stock Price Movements of Finns Engaging in Iarge Acquisitions," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 7 ("arch, 1972): 1474. James F. Nielsen and Ronald W. Velicher, "A Financial Analysis of Acquisition and Merger Premiums," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 8 (F’arch, 1973): 146. Ibid. Michael Bradley, "Interfirm Tender Offers and the Varket for Corporate Control," Journal of Business 40 (October, 1980): 346. "The Morning After - Most of the Stockholders Who Accepted Those Fancy Tender Offers Now Have Reason to Regret Their Taste," Forbes, 1 February 1970, pp. 15-16. Weston ani Rice, p. 746. Baker, P~1iller,and Pamsparger, p. 56. Stanley Block, "The Merger Impact on Stock Price F’ovements," "SU Business Topics 17 (Spring, 1969): 11. CHAPTER III The Plan of Research A. Rationale for the Use of Financial Ratios Analysts find financial ratios to be appealing for several reasons. 1) Financial information is publicly available for analysis of publicly traded corporations because of Federal security disclosure regulations. 2) Financial ratios provide measurements of a firm's growth in earnings and asset size, debt capacity, efficiency, and dividend policy. 3) Ratios compare a given firm's performance within an industry, or to firms within other industries because the ratios are designed to provide comparability by relating the above attributes to the size of the firm measured by sales, earnings, asset size, or number of shares of common stock outstanding. 4) Numerous investment advisory services rely extensively upon various financial ratios. Given that financial ratios are pOpular, widely used, and readily available, how successful are they as an analytic device? In appraising ratio usefulness to investors, O'Connor found that univariate ratio analysis would not be useful in differentiating between common stocks primarily because of the semi-strong form of the efficient markets pricing mechanism. " . . . even on a multivariate basis ratios might be found to be of questionable usefulness in the prediction of return rankings for common stocks."1 110 111 Beaver believes the evidence "overwhelmingly" suggests a difference in the ratios of failed and non-failed firms,2 that the ratios can be useful in the prediction of failure for at least five years before the failure,3 and that the most commonly used ratios would possess little utility because they are most often manipulated by managenent.4 Beaver also suspects that a multi-ratio analysis can predict better than the single ratios, but his results did not verify that hypothesis.5 Neter criticized Beaver's sample design suggesting that the non-failed firms sample be as large as possible for more precise information . 6 Horrigan contended that, regarding bond ratings, "ratios are not likely to be efficient predictors of dependent variables which shift in a random pattern over time such as stock market prices, because the financial ratios tend to be highly correlated over time.7 However, he did conclude that the general approach ought to be that of a multiple regression, rather than a univariate analysis, and that accounting data and financial ratios have been found to be useful for determination of corporate-bond ratings. The multivariate approach used by Finches and Mingo [111] in their bond rating study provided further support for his conclusion. Iev [13] has cautioned users of financial ratios in the application of financial ratios. Summarizing these limitations he cautions against univariate analysis, misaveraging ratios, misinter- preting ratio changes, and other faulty uses of percentages. The conclusion is that it seems the use of multivariate discriminant analysis on financial ratios provides better results in terms of predictive abilities than presumed. There are explanations for 112 this, which are discussed in part 0 of this chapter. B. Ratios Included in This Study The purposes of this section of the paper are threefold: 1) review financial ratios used in the previous studies by S“, Stevens, and Belkacui; 2) present an additional set of ratios; and 3) discuss their expected importance in light of the preceding discussion of the theory of mergers . Profitability Iev erage : Activity: Other : T"inanc ial Ratio F81 FR2 FR? FR4 W5 FR6 PR7 FR1 8 PR1 9 PR9 IRAQ F'R11 FRZO FR12 FR13 ER14 FR15 FR16 IR17 Table 3-1 Ratios Studied Author Ratio Employing Earnings Before Interest and taxes / Total Assets S Cross Profits / Sales S Farni 3 Before Interest and Taxes Sales S Net Income / Sales S Earnings Before Taxes /Sales S Net Income / Stockholders lbuity B,S Net Income / Total Assets B,S Cash Flow / Net hbrth B Cash Flow/ Total Assets B Long Term Debt / “-‘arket Value 8 Common Equity Long Term Debt / Book Value Common Equity Iong Term Debt / Total Assets S Total Liabilities / Total Assets S long Term Debt 4» Preferred Stock B / Total Assets Sales / Total Assets S Cost of Goods Sold / Inventory S Sales / Quick Current Assets S Interest Expense / Cash Plus Farketable Securities S Dividend Payout Percentage S‘J,S Price / Farnings Ratio s1 s 113 1111 FR21 Total Assets liquidity: PR22 Current Assets / Total Assets B FR23 Cash / Total Assets B FR24 Net Working Capital / Tbtal Assets B,S FR25 QuiCk Current Assets / Current Assets B PR26 Current Ratio B FR27 Acid Test Ratio B FR28 Cash / Current liabilities B FR29 Current Assets / sales B PR3O Quick Current Assets / sales B 11131 Net Working Capital / Sales B,s* *The capital letter indicates which of the authors discussed used these ratios. B indicates the Belkaoui Study, SM indicates the Simkowitz- MOnroe Study, and S indicates Stevens ratios used in.his dissertation, published article, or in both. 145 The above ratios were selected because of their popularity in the literature. Quoting Belkacui:8 They represent the 'traditional' categories in ratio analysis: balance sheet ratios . . . income statement ratios . . . , and mixed ratios. . . . their possible relevance to the takeover phenomenon; . . . [and] . . . their appearance in the literature as indicators of the ability of a firm to avoid takeovers. Additionally one other set of ratios is introduced. "hat set includes five ratios which examine specific attributes on a per share basis relative to the year-end closing price of the firm' 8 common stock. The closing price is incorporated into the ratio because the price of the common stock should influence the likelihood of the acquisition of a company. Those ratios are illustrated in Table 3-2. The sixth ratio, sales to fixed assets, reflects the impact of companies contending it is cheaper to buy existing assets than to build new assets . Table 5-2 Add it ional Rat ios Stud ied FR32 Closing Price / Book Value Per Siare IR33 Closirg Price / Cash Per Share BR54 Closing Price / Net Working Capital Per Share FR35 Closing Price / Quick Net Working Capital Per Share FR36 Tax loss Carry Forward Per Snare / Closirg Price PR37 Sales / Net Fixed Assets *************** 116 C. Rationale for the Use of Discriminant Functions There is substantial precedence for the methodology employed in the present study. Piultivariate discriminant analysis (RDA hereafter) was first employed by the scientists Fisher [56] for taxonomic uses and Bernard [31] in measuring Egyptian skull sizes. The first financial application was by Durand [48] to differentiate between "good" and "bad" consumer loan applicants. Walter [128] classified firms into high and low price earnings ratio groups. Ayers and Fbrgy [103] developed a numerical credit evaluation system. Smith [121] classified firms into standard investment categories. Finches and Mingo [111] used FDA to determine bond ratings of long term debt. Altman [26] predicted corporate bankruptcies through financial ratio analysis. Since then Gabhart [134] used FDA to predict municipal government insolvency in Michigan, and deister [50] attempted to predict bankruptcies of small firms. FDA has distinct advantages to other forms of analysis. First, in using VEDA the researcher is able to analyze simultaneously the entire variable profile of an object to be tested rather than by univariate analysis. Univariate analysis is unable to provide two distinct advantages of MDA: (1) MDA calculates covariances between the financial ratios being tested and (2) also is capable of indicating which ratios are more important. Most MBA studies of a financial nature provide results which are dissimilar to results obtained from the use of univariate analysis. In most instances there are clear differences in the selection of most important ratios to predict an event. Examples of the superiority of MDA in the literature are so common it is not helpful to reference them here . 117 Another advantage of FDA, as opposed to multiple regression, is MDA's ability to use qualitative dependent variables such as bankrupt or solvent, good or poor credit risk, or is the firm an acquisition candidate. that is FDA, and how has it been used in merger studies? It is a statistical technique which classified observations of several a priori groupings based on certain characteristics. A linear MBA is an attempt to derive a linear combination of these characteristics which best "discriminates" between two groups. The discriminant function is of the form Z = be + b1X1 + b2X2 . . . ann where bO is a constant used to adjust for the grand means, (see necks [12], p. 443). hi, (i =1 . . . n), are the discriminant coefficients of independent variable characteristics, Xi’ (i = 1 . . . n) , and Z is the value which is then used to classify the object into the two or more groups. See Altman, [26] Morrison [99], or Greene [7] for excellent discussions of FDA. There have been previous attempts to use FDA to identify merger candidates. In Canada, Belkaoui [34] used discriminant functions on data from 1960 to 1968 on twenty-five industrial firms listed on the Toronto Stock l'kchange. In a larger study, Singh used FDA and financial ratios to predict mergers in the Unite Kingdom, from 1955-1967 [20,119]. In the United States, there were also to studies using NBA and financial ratios to identify merger candidates. rI‘hese studies by Simkowitz and Monroe (8‘1) [118] and by Stevens [1'55]. though done at about the same time, reached dissimilar conclusions. It is possible that the dissimilarities were attributable to the differing nature and methodologies of their studies. Si". focused specifically on 118 conglomerate mergers and reached a ratio profile using a step wise regression procedure. Stevens' study of mergers was not confined to conglomerates, and he used a factor analysis to reduce the set of ratios to a best set. Both SM and Stevens called for follow-up studies in a different time period, to test for continuity of the best set of ratios.9 An attempt to resolve the dissimilar conclusions reached by the two studies is overdue. The new sample used in my study tests specifically for the existence of such best set continuity, and will assist in the determination of the better dimension reduction technique in this application, factor analysis or discriminant analysis. D. Statistical Limitations of This Study There has been considerable discussion on the necessary statistical assumptions and experimental design requirements using financial applications of MDA [52,70]. NEDA requires that the discriminating variables have multivariate normal distributions and the variables have equal variance-covariance matrices within each of the groups. Morrison [99] and others have indicated the importance of the equal variance-covariance matrices; it is a prerequisite of the linear MDA model. 'Ihe test for equality is Bartlett's Box M test, to be discussed in detail later. Rejection of the hypothesis that the matrices are equal suggests use of a quadratic EDA function, an extremely complex undertaking, which according to Singh, " . . . raise[s] very awkward problems and [has] proved rather intractable in practice."10 In a study by Marks and Dunn, the decision rule of unequal covariance matrices precluiing a linear MDA function is clouded by 149 efficiency trade-offs with sample sizes. When sample sizes are small and the number of variables relatively large , linear rules may give more efficient estimates of the expected error rates than quadratic rules even when the population dispersions are unequal.11 When sample sizes are large, Klecka believes FDA to be robust to violations of the equal covariance requirement [12]. 'Ehe other considerations are misinterpretation of the significance of the coefficients of the independent variables, reduction in dimensionality, group definition problems, inappropriate a priori probabilities , misestimation of classification error rates, use of split samples, and misinterpretations of classification tables. All of these will be considered in great detail in Chapter IV which discusses the findings of this study. E. Rationale for a Dimension Reduction The chief purpose of a dimension reduction in this study is to eliminate those financial ratios which do not contribute to the TTDA function's overall ability to classify merger or non-merger candidates. As Eisenbeiss observed: "This can be particularly important for problems in . . . finance when it is often possible to generate a large number of variables which need to be pared down to some manageable size."11 Such an approach is not at all uncommon. Both the Stevens and 8-" studies reduced substantially the number of ratios in their final model. SP? began with twenty-four ratios, and eliminated twenty of them.” Stevens began with twenty ratios and eliminated sixteen of then in a factor analysis.” Financial ratios of a firm tend to exhibit high correlations over 50 time. Because of this correlation, dimension reduction techniques are able to eliminate many of the ratios without losing much, if any, of the discriminating capabilities of the model. rl‘he difficult question is which ratios to use. Critics of the process by which one begins with many ratios, reducing their numbers to a few, fail to provide a rationale for using specific ratios, ex ante. mr example, hypothesizing that above average profitability improves the probability of a firm's subsequent acquisition necessitates selecting one or more profitability ratios. Should the researcher select net income after taxes divided by common stockholders equity (return on equity)? Doing so disregards asset size (rate of return on assets) , market value of common equity, and efficiency (rate of return on sales). As a result you must begin the study with all four ratios to determine which, if any, are most useful, eliminating any or all of them in a dimension reduction process. Another example: i-ferger literature suggests that firms likely to be acquired have excessive liquidity. Which liquidity ratio is the best to use? Care must be exercised since some evidence suggests that managements manipulate the more popular ratios.15 That may provide one explanation as to why neither current ratios nor acid-test ratios failed to discriminate in Altman's study of bankruptcies. "Of the three liquidity ratios evaluated, [net working capital to total assets, current ratio, and acid-test ratios], this one [net working capital] proved to be the most valuable."16 "The working capital/ total assets ratio showed greater statistical significance both on a univariate and multivariate 133,315."?7 “"ost financial texts emphasize acid test and current ratios. Finally, arbitrarily deciding which ratios to use ex ante may 51 reduce the utility of an MDA's most desirable feature, its ability to classify data into subsets by analyzing its ratios simultaneously. The two most commonly used dimension reductions are factor analysis and stepwise regressions. Both of these techniques have several variations. The Statistical Package for the Social Sciences (SPSS) [12] has five variations of Stepwise methods. 'Ihe SPSS factor analysis package contains at least nine combinations of factor analysis. Brief discussions of fector analysis are in SPSS [12] and Greene [7]. An extended discussion is in Harmon.[10]. An important part of this study will be to use both procedures as part of an attempt to reconcile the differences between S!" and Stevens' findings. One explanation for these contradictions could be the different treatment of the multicollinearity problem in the studies. It is not known whether differences in financial ratios due to differing statistical procedures will: 1) weaken the general worth of the financial model, or 2) diminish the userIness of'one of'the dimension reduction techniques . 1. 2. 8. 10. Footnotes Chapter III Melvin O'Connor, "()1 the Usefulness of Financial Patios to Investors in Common Stock," The Accounting Review 48 (April, 1973): 351. William H. Beaver, "Financial Ratios As Predictors of Failure," Journal of Accounting Research 4 (Supplement, 1966): 81. Ibid, p. 102. Ibid, pp. 79—81. Ibid, p. 100. John Neter, "Discussion of Financial Ratios as Predictors of Failure," Journal of Accounting Research 4 (Supplement, 1966): 114. James O. Horrigan, "Ellie Determination of long-Term Credit Standing with Financial Ratios," Journal of Accounting Research 4 (Supplement, 1966): 48-49. Ahmed Belkaoui, "Financial Ratios as Predictors of Canadian Takeovers," Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 5 (Spring, 1978): 95. Michael Simkowitz and Robert J. Monroe, "A Discriminant Analysis Function for Conglomerate Targets," 6 Southern Journal of Business (November, 1971): 14. Donald lee Stevens, "A Multivariate Analysis of Financial Characteristics of Acquired Firms in Industrial Mergers," (Ph.D. dissertation, Michigan State University, 1972): 116. Ajit Singh, Takeovers; Their Relevance to the Stock Market and the Theory of the Firm, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1971). p- 91. 52 11. 12. 13. 140 15. 16. 17. 53 Robert A. Eisenbeiss, Problems in Applyng Discriminant Analysis in Credit Scoring Y‘A’Todels (Federal Reserve Bulletin, [197fl), p. 16. Idem, "Pitfalls in the Application of Discriminant Analysis in Business, Finance and Fcononics," Journal of Finance 32 (June, 1977): 885. Simkowitz and Vonroe, "A Discriminant Analysis Function," pp. 9, 13’ 14. Stevens, "A Multivariate Analysis," pp. 152, 154, 157. Beaver, "Financial Ratios as Predictors," pp.78—79. Edward I. Altman, "Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis, and the Prediction of Corporate Bankruptcy," Journal of Finance 23 (September, 1968): 594. Ibid. Chapter IV Data Analysis and Sample Design A . Data Selection This study investigates a sample of one thousand four hundred and fifty five companies which have been divided into four subsets of data. ’Ihe first subset consists of two hundred thirty five firms which were acquired in the time period 1970 through 1976. This data was extracted from the Compustat Research File, a computer accessed data base consisting of up to twenty years of financial information pertaining to firms removed iron the Compustat Industrial File [133]. Del istings from the Industrial File are caused by any of several financial events; the appropriate event here is the acquisition of a firm which, prior to the event, was included in the Industrial File. The Industrial File is the source of the second data subset. It is also a computer accessed data base providing up to twenty years of financial data for several thousand publicly traded firms. The second data subset consists of three hundred twenty three companies. This subset, the control group, was randomly sampled and was from the same time period as the data from the first subset. The only modifications to the randomly sampled control group came as a result of two problems. 1. Because the control group was of the period 1970-1976, some of these firms were subsequently acquired. The control group has been 514 55 verified to ensure all merged firms have been deleted as of July, 1981. 2. Forty eight1 companies were removed from the randomly sampled control group because their industries employed accounting methods which were incompatible with some of the ratios used in this study. These industries included banks, savings and loan institutions, insurance companies, and utilities. Consequently, a deficiency in this test is its inability to be generalized to include industries whose accounting definitions are inapplicable to some of the thirty seven financial ratios used in this test. Any test of those industries will require new ratios which will conform with those accounting procedures. The third subset is a sample of fifty two firms whose mergers occurred in 1979. Information obtained from this subset is an important contribution to this study for several reasons: The fourth subset is a sample of eight-hundred—forty-five non- acquired firms, used as a control group. Their financial data preceding 1979 is analyzed as a contrast to the third subset. The third and fourth subsets provide a. test of the predictive power of the discriminant fumtion generated from the combination of the first two subsets. Both the Stevens and SW studies recommended updates to test their model and to determine if the same ratios would be useful in any time period. Second, rarely in FDA literature are there ex ante tests of a discriminant function. Generally data are separated into two groups, the first group is used to generate a discriminant fimction, and the latter group is then classified, expost. Then the model is then evaluated as to its predictive powers in an expost test. Joy and Tollefson and others have criticized such previous MDA applied studies stressing: "Ix post discrimination may provide a useful foundation for 56 explanation of the past, but it does not provide sufficient evidence for concluiing that the future can be predicted ."2 Finally, this study evaluates ratios cross-sectionally over time, armually for three years prior to the merger. One of the objectives of this study is to determine if a few ratios will be sufficiently important to appear in the discriminant functions from all three years prior to a target firm's ultimate acquisition. Three years is suggested because management may need considerable lead time to restructure its firm's financial characteristics to fend off potential acquirers, and three years also acknowledges Belkaoui's results [34]. There are other reasons for reducing the number of financial ratios used to isolate merger candidates aside from the principle of parsimony. Some articles have suggested that firms have obvious financial characteristics which make them vulnerable. "Fanagement should realize: many if not most of the takeovers or tenders could have been foreseen by looking at the victim's published financial data."3 Vance claimed to have predicted seventeen of twenty one mergers by using four ratios. His ex post study focused on price-earnings levels, net working capital to total assets, long term debt to net worth, and earnings per share growth rates.4 A deficiency of his study is that he did not test his model ex ante. Other researchers disagree with Vance, advocating other key ratios, or that the merger selection card idate process cannot be generalized, in other words, each merger has unique aspects and therefore may not be easily predicted.5 A second objective of this study is to identify trends in the importance of ratios over the three year span prior to a target's 57 acquisition. Finally, this study will comment on the timing and significance of the appearance of key ratios, update previous tests in other eras, and resolve the contradictions in the literature. Twenty accounting measurements have been selected, includirg such items as sales, depreciation, long term debt, earnings per share, and market price for the common stock. The twenty items were selected because of their expected importance in measuring the attractiveness of a potential acquisition. Using this accounting data, the thirty seven financial ratios identified in Chapter III were then calculated. Because of the unique nature of this test, the cross sectional ratio analysis, three, two and one year(s) prior to a merger, a computer program written in Ibrtran IV was used to retrieve the accounting data from the first two subsets and calculate the thirty seven financial ratios. Those ratios were accessed from a data file and, using a standard packaged program, were used to produce three discriminant functions. The discriminant analysis program was Subprogram Discriminant, written for the Statistical Package for Social Scientists (eras) [12]. A necessary assumption in the use of FDA is that the populations are multivariate normally distributed. If the two groups in this particular case have different means (centroids), but identical variance-covariance matrices, then a linear multiple discriminant analysis provides an optimal solution to the classification problem. Figure 4—1 is an elementary graphical illustration of a two group analysis. A and B represent scatter diagrams of two groups, merged and Figure 4-1 / ' l A / I B' l D ISCRIMINAN T FYI NCTION Z Graphical Illustration of Two-Group Discriminant Analysis from Hair, et al [ 8]. 58 59 nonmerged firms. In addition we have two measurements, X1 and X2 for each member of the two groups. The ellipses drawn around groups A and B usually enclose a predetermined prOportion of the observations, generally 95% or more of each group. Because the ellipses usually overlap, the objective is to draw a straight line which minimizes the amount of overlap. The new axis Z expresses the two-variable profiles of groups A and B as single numbers, the discriminant scores. By finding a linear combination of the original variable X1 and X2, we can project the result as discriminant Z scores on a single axis. For a lengthier discussion of this see either [2] or [7]. It is important to emphasize that unless the variances and covariance matrices between the two groups are equal, you cannot construct a straight line to separate the two groups, because the ellipses, also referred to as centours, will lack equal shape and orientation, and unequally shaped centours may weaken one' s conclusions. Inability to create a linear discriminant function suggests use of a quadratic discriminant function. Several authors have countered that large sample sizes will make linear discriminant functions robust to violations of the equal variance-covariance requirements.6 In this particular study the requirements are subjected to that debate. The null hypothesis: Ho: “12 = 022 Results shown in Table 4-1 Show that the variance-covariance matrices are clearly unequal. Table 4-1 Fisher's Box 1"! Test for Equal Covariances arm STATISTICAL SIGNIFICANCE LAG 2 (t-5) .oooo IAG 1 (t—2) o. LAG o (t-1) 0. Table 4—1 results were obtained through the Statistic 7 of the SPSS Subprogram DISCRD-‘DEART. Given the large sample sizes, and their supposed contribution to the robustness of violations of the equal covariance requirement it was decided to temporarily disregard these Box FF scores and assess their importance in the conclusion of this paper. A more important statistical procedure is to split the total sample into two groups. One group is used to generate a discriminant function to be used to classify the members in the second group, the validation group, because use of a single combined sample imparts an upward bias in the overall classification success. In this test, the firm' 3 Cusip number dictated the group. Bren numbered Cusip firms were used to produce a discriminant function, and odd numbered Cusip firms were then used as the validation sample in this split sample technique. Readers may wish to read W'orrison [99] Frank, Tassey, and T-"orrison [57], Joy and Tollefson [70] or Fisenbeiss [52] for additional discussion on the problem of bias. 6O Table 4—2 (a) Classification Results - Hold Out Group Split Sample Analysis and Validation IAG 2 (t43) Actual Predicted Tie rged Eon-“ferged 1! of cases it (a) r (d) Then Verged 101 74 (73.3) 27 (26.7) Analysis Group mien lTon—‘Terged 150 39 (30.0) 91 (70.0) total classification = (n11 + n22) / n.. = 71.49? Acttel Predicted Odd lierged 105 55 (52-4) 50 (47.6] validation Group Odd Non-Merged 128 41 (32.0) 87 (68.0) total classification = (55 + 87) / 233 = 60.9": 61 62 Results between the two sets of tests are consistent with the bias discussion. The reader should note the lower total classification success produced by the odd numbered merged firms in the validation group when compared to the even numbered merged firms in the analysis group (52.4% vs. 75.5%). Also note the slightly lower total classification success, 60.991, in the validation (hold out) group compared to the analysis group, 71.4%. The 71.4% produced in the analysis group incorporates the bias inherent in the process of usiru: a sample twice, once for a discriminant function, and then using the same data in a classification process. The actual total classification success is the 60.9%, the success of classifying observations not used in the generation of the discriminant function. The next step in the classification process is to determine if the 60.9% could have been obtained by a random process. There are three methods used to test for statistically acceptable classification accuracy. Total classificationfinn + n22) / mg] is one of the three measures of classification, and is considered to be superior to the other two measures, maximum chance and proportional chance classifications . Maximum chance is a naive model which assigns all observations to the largest group, which in this study is non—merged firms. Maximum chance in the IAG 2 model in Table 4-2(a) is: [(n21 + n22) / n..] =[(41 + 87) /255] = .549 frequency of non-merged firms The maximum chance procedure avoids the central issues of identifying both merged and non-merged firms. It may be useful if 63 sample sizes are clearly unequal, but that is not the situation in this part of the study. The other classification measure, proportional chance, does attempt to identify merged firms. (loservations are randomly assigned to either group with probabilities equal to group frequencies. The model for this, using LAG 2 is {um,+mp/nnfi+[mm+n2)/mjfi {[(55 + 50) / 23312 + [(41 + 87) #23312} 0-505 p The objective is to test total classification success against maximum chance or proportional chance results. The test statistic used to establish that a discriminant function used on a validation sample produces results better than pure chance is: 0-? p(1-p) ”2 n.., where C = total classification success and p = probability of success n.. = total sample size if p = maximum chance, then p =(n2. / n..): .549 or if p = pr0p0rtional chance, then P =[(n1,/n--)2 + (“2./"")2]= .505 611 Z has a t—distribution with n—1 degrees of freedom. To test the IAG 2 model first against maximum chance, .609 - .549 Z = = 1.8404 (.549) x (.451) 1/2 233 and t(120)(.05) = 1.658 t(°°)(.005) = 1.645 t(120)(.025) =1.9e t(o°)(.025) = 1.96 So the model is significant at least at the .05 level. Testing the IAG 2 model against the proportional chance model, .609 '- 0505 .104 z = = = 5.175 (505) X (495) 1/2 0328 233 which is significant at .005. IAG 2 is superior to random chance in classifying merged from non- merged firms, evaluated either by maximum chance or by proportional chance classification methods. LAG 1 and IAG 0 model total classification results were then tested. They are illustrated in Table 4-2(b) and Table 4-2(c), respectively. Analysis Group validation Group 65 Table 4-2 (continued) 4-2(b) IAG 1 (t—2) Classification Results - Hold Out Group, Actual Predicted Her ed Non—Merged 4 of cases # 7%) # (34) Even Verged 105 75 (71.4) 30 (28.6) Even Non-Merged 131 42 (32.1) 89 (67.?) total analysis classification rate = 69.5% Odd Verged 109 60 (55.0) 49 (45.0) Odd anr"erged 128 40 (31.2) 88 (68.8) total validation classification rate = 62.4% M'aximum chance significance 2.5946; significant at .001 Proportional chance significance 3.7256; .0005 significant at Analysis Group validation Group 66 Table 4-2 (Continued) Table 4-2 (c) LAG 0 (t—1) Classification Results - Hold Out Group Split Sample Analysis and Validation Actual Predicted P'er ed Non-Tierged :14 of cases 21‘ 6(3) # (:17) Even Verged 101 72 (71.5) 29 (28.7) Ellen Non-"erged 119 35 (29.4) 84 (70.6) total classification = (n11 + n22) / n.. = 70.99? Actual Predicted Odd .‘-"‘erged 108 54 (575.0) 54 (50.0) Odd lTon-T'Terged 123 33 (26.8) 90 (73.2) total classification e n11 + n22) / n.. = 62.5% Faximum chance significance = 2.2542; significant at (.025) Proportional chance significance = 3.1614; significant at (.005) 67 LAG 2 through IAG 0 models all demonstrate significant success in classifying merged from non-merged firms. Because of this success further analysis is warranted. The discriminant functions generated were then used as an ex ante predicting model to identify from the third subset the fifty two mergers subsequently occurring in 1979. Table 4q2 illustrates the three discriminant functions produced in this merger study. Overall classification success is 60.94%, 62.4575, and 62.34% respectively three, two, and one year prior to the merger. The next step in the process was to establish that an T‘TDA application would successfully separate merged from non—merged figures. Table 4-3 illustrates that success. The process used was Method Direct, an application of Subprogram DISCRBIINANT in SPSS. Method Direct evaluates all thirty-seven ratios utilized herein, rejecting only those ratios which do not contribute at all to the classification process. It is not a dimension reduction technique. 68 Table 4-3 Descriptive Statistics “Tethod Direct Discriminant Functions.7 Standardized Coefficients LAG2 LAG1 LAGO LAGZFR1 -.061 91 LAG1FR1 . 23132 LAGOFR1 LAG2FR2 .33838 LAG1FR2 .48432 LAGOFR2 LAGZF'R3 -. 42686 LAG1FR3 -.44488 LAGO'F‘R5 LAGZFR4 .09824 LAG1FR6 . 31 565 LAGO'TR6 LAG2E‘R5 .07141 LAG1FR8 -. 10632 LAGOFR7 LAGZFR6 . 10458 LAG1FR9 .46799 LAGO’TRB LAGZTR7 -. 521 a) IAG1FR1O .31837 LAGOTR9 LAGZTRB . 20954 LAG1FR11 -. 05036 LAGOFR10 LAGZFR10 -.38742 LAG1FR13 .08670 LAGOFR12 LAGZFR1 1 .05038 LAG1FR14 -. 45712 LAGO'TR13 LAG2FR12 -. 26097 G1FR15 . 2271 6 LAGOI-‘R1 4 LAGZFR13 -. 08102 LAG1FR16 . 30748 LAGOFR15 LAGZFR1 4 .00406 LAG1FR17 . 22564 LAGO'FI‘R1 6 LAGZFR15 -. 31 61 6 LAG1FR21 .74891 LAG07R17 LAG2FR16 -. 13294 IAG1FR22 . 41 224 LAGOFR21 LAG2FR17 . 17755 IAG1FR23 . 00488 LAGOFR22 LAGZFR21 -. 66853 IAG1FR25 .09492 LAGOFR23 LAG2T“R22 -. 10038 LAG1FR26 -. 67727 LAGOFRZS LAGZ“R23 -. 281 29 LAG1FR27 .88073 LAGOT‘R26 LAG2FR25 .15351 LAG1FR28 . 14003 LAGOFR27 LAGZTR26 -. 2591 2 LAG1FR32 -. 38629 LAGOFR28 LAGZFR27 .04462 LAG1FR35 -. 21 1 8) LAGOFR29 LAG2’7R28 -. 00841 LAG1FR36 . 23947 LAGOFR3O LAG-2FR29 -. 33457 LAGOFR31 LAG2"R30 -. 13142 LAGOFR32 LAG2FR31 . 1 1064 LAGOFR33 LAG273‘R32 . 21 876 LAGOI-‘R34 LAGZFR33 .46396 LAGOTR35 LAG2VR34 . 29540 LAGOT’R36 LAGZTR35 —. 10608 LAGO‘P‘R37 LAGZFR36 -.11580 LAGZ‘R37 -.02250 wILrs Lambda8 Chi Square9 (Significance) Lag 2 leg 1 Lag 0 Lag 2 leg 1 leg 0 .8223 .8740 .8144 85.21 61.29 87.16 ( .0000) ( .0000) ( .0000) 69 The three discriminant functions are all successful in classifying merged and non—merged firms given their Wilks lambdas, Chi Square Statistics and their resulting significance levels. Therefore, further analysis, using the data and this methodology is warranted. B. Characteristics of the Data The data analyzed in this test came from publicly traded firms which are, or were previously sufficiently large, to be included in the Compustat Industrial File at some time during the 1970's. To illustrate, Table 4-4 compares accounting data between merged and non-merged firms: Table 4-4 SIZE CHARACTIRISTICS COTPARISON Averages and 953’: Confidence Intervals Between '"erged and Non-lierged Firms (Isa 0) F-"erged Non-merged Sales $195 million $595 million 955% CI ($144w‘5246 million) ($477-$711 million) Total Assets $143 million $699 mill ion 95% CI ($10045175 million) (55569-829 million) Net Income Before Extraordinary Items 3‘6 million 3330 million 95% CI (($40>—$135 million) (($287>—$397 million) Clearly, merged firms tend to be smaller, measured by sales and assets. Income tended to be less for merged firms, but there is not a clear separation here . Chapter IV Fbotnotes The breakdown was as follows: SIC Code 4911-4931: 21 cases 6021 -6027: 16 cases 6120: 4 cases 6312: 6 cases 3714: 1 case “aurice 0. Joy and John 0. Tollefson, "0n the Financial Applications of Discriminant Analysis," Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 10 (December, 1975): 727. Jack 0. Vance, "Is Your Company A Take-Over Target?" Harvard Business view, May-June, 1969. P. 93. Ibid, p. 94. Fbr example, read Greenhill's remarks in "The Profit Potential in Spotting Takeovers," Business Week, 24 October 1977, p.100. Ibr example, see William R. ’{l ecka, "Discriminant Analysis," Chapter 23, Statistical Paclgge for the Social Sciences, 2nd ed., ed. Norman H. Nie, C. ladley Bull, Jean G. Jenkins Varin Steinbrenner and Dale R. Bent (mew York: 'TcGraw—Hill, 1975): 455. The IAG 2 discriminant function reports standardized coefficients (each coefficient is divided by its standard deviation) generated from financial information three years prior to acquisition of the firms in the sample group. Wilks lambda is an inverse measure of the discriminating power of the financial ratios in the discriminant functions which have not yet been removed by the discriminant functions. The Wilks lambda is distributed as a Chi Square statistic. Chi square significance levels of .0000 are highly significant. 70 Chapter v Findings of the Study A. Distad's Reduced Dimension Model Using Discriminant Analys is Aside from the principle of parsimony, application of the thirty-seven ratio discriminant function discussed in Chapter Iv would be a cumbersome technique to isolate merger candidates. Therefore a statistical screening process which removes financial ratios that do not contribute significantly to the classification process is warranted. The objective is to reduce the number of variables to a few "key" ratios. Because there are several dimension reduction techniques, one of the important aspects of this paper is to determine whether various dimension reduction techniques produce conflicting sets of best ratios. Stevens, using factor analysis, and Simkowitz and Fonroe (Sz‘i'), using FDA, contributed studies of financial characteristics of merged firms during the 1960's, but the two studies produced conflicting results. Stevens suggested one possible explanation was the differing statistical methodology. These methods are two of the most commonly employed dimension reduction techniques used with discriminant analysis. First using a stepwise discriminant function, the key ratios for the 1970's test of the new mergers were reduced to the following: 71 72 Table 5-1 Reduced Dimension Descriptive Statistics Reduced Discriminant Functions, Standardized Coefficients LAG2 LAG1 (fl-3) (1)-2) IAG2FR3 . 56385 LAG1E7R1 .42015 LAG2FR4 -. 63142 LAG1FR6 . 27666 LAG2FR7 . 56227 LAG1FR9 . 4571 1 LAGZFR10 .30075 LAG1FR15 .52839 LAGZE’R1 2 .30911 LAG1FR16 .30978 LAGZFR15 .33268 LAG1FR17 -. 21650 LAG2TR21 .70744 LAG1FR21.£{)609 LAGZIR23 . 26278 IAG1FR22 .16558 LAGZFR26 . 20596 LAG1FR26 . 21434 LAG2FR29 . 29725 LAG1FR32 -. 34656 LAGZFR32 -. 20991 LAG1T‘R33 -. 55826 LAGZF‘R33 -. 49384 LAG1FR34 . 28398 LAGZFR34 -. 26886 LAG11~‘R35 -.1E338 LAG1FR36 . 21 101 WILVS Lambda Chi quare lag 2 leg 1 Leg 0 leg 2 .8524 .8615 .8243 (.0000) LAGO (t-1 ) LAGOVPJ .36CX)2 LAGO7‘F5 -. 251 37 LAGOVR7 -. 70662 LA COWS -. 27681 1151130789 -. 181 24 LAGO‘R1 4 -.15701 LAGOTTR1 5 -. 21962 LAGOT"R1 7 .86217 LAGOT‘R1 8 -. 42766 LAGOVR21 -. 66200 LAGCVR25 -. 25428 LAGOFR27 -.12971 IAGCFR36 -. 37275 LAGOF‘R37 .2761 7 (Significance) , 1 leg 0 ( .0000) ( .0000) 73 Table 5-2 Distad's Reduced Dimension Classification "atrices Table 5-2( a) leg 2 (t-3) Actual Predicted Merged lion- P’erged .41 (a) 4 (so Verged 121 (55) 99 (45) lion—Tierged 57 (21) 213 (79) Overall Classification Success: 68¢ l'aximum Chance Classification Significance: Proportional Chance Classification Significance: Type I Frror Rate: Type II Error Rate: 5.786 vs. 3.373 at (.0005) 7.748 vs. 3.373 at (.0005) 45:13- 21% 74 Table 5-2(b) Ias 1 (fr-2) W Predicted l-"erged Non—F-‘erged # (%) # (5) Merged 107 (47) 119 (53) NOanerged 63 (24) 200 (76) Overall Classification Success: 63% 1'8me Chance Classification Significance: 4.02 vs. 3.373 at (.0005) Proporational Chance Classification Significance: 5.57 vs. 3.373 at (.0005) Type I Error Rate: 5395 Type II Error Rate: 2495 75 Table 5-2( 0) Leg 0 (ft—1) Actual Predicted P'erged Non—"erged ,3 (9‘4) (7‘ (£75) T’erged 122 (56) 96 (44) lion-'vierged 44 (18) 200 (82) Overall Classification Success: 70"? I’aximm Chance Classification Significance: Proportional Chance Classification Significance: Type I Iirror Rate: Type II Frror Rate: 7.39 vs. 3.373 at (.0005) 8.51 vs. 3.373 at (.0005) 44% 18>? 76 Use of a stepwise discriminant function, Rao V from the SPSS Subprogram DISCRBTIFAITT has produced a set of three models, LAG 2 through LAG 0, and variables which have been reduced to thirteen, fourteen, and fifteen respectively from the original thirty—seven ratios. All three models are significant at very high levels (.0000). The next procedure is to employ a factor analysis, the version used here was the SPSS Subprogram FACTOR. B. Distad's Reduced Dimension lo’odel Using Factor Analysis The objective of a factor analysis is to explore the possibility of dimension reduction by constructing a set of new variables on the basis of interrelations exhibited among the original thirty seven financial ratios included in this study. Using factor analysis, Stevens' original variable list was reduced from twenty ratios to four or five ratios. Che objective of this paper is to attempt to update his work using factor analysis as a comparison with an I'IEDA originated dimension reduction process. The factor analysis process transforms a set of variables into a new set of variables which are uncorrelated with each other. The new set of variables is a linear combination which accounts for more of the variance in the data than any other linear combination of variables. The general model is: Zj = 83:11:11 + 83-21312 '1' o o o + ajn FYI Where: j = 1,2,...,n observed variables Z = variable j, in this case FRJ- Rn = uncorrected components, each as a linear combination of the n original variables aji = factor loading (the standardized multiple 77 regression coefficient of variable j on factor i) The SE8 Subprogram FACTOR was used for this test, factor loadings were established using the principal components method (PA1), and these factors were rotated by the varimax method. The principal components process was selected because it is most commonly used; Cooley and Iohnes believe the varimax solution is superior to other rotation procedures.1 Table 5-3(a) is the IAG 0 factor rotation and percent of variance accounted for by each of the factors. In addition the table presents the cumulative percent of variance by the sum of the factors. Tables 5- 3(b) is the IAG 1 analysis, and 5—3(c) is the IAG 2 analysis. 78 'T‘able 5-3(a) Lid 0 (t-1) Factor Analysis, Tigenvalues and Rercent of Variance FACTOR FIGTVALUT PC? 0'" WP. CUT PCT 1 7.26371 19.6 19.6 2 4.82608 13.0 32.7 3 3.73049 10.1 42.8 4 3.12730 8.5 51.2 5 2.24859 6.1 57.3 6 2.19263 5.9 63.2 7 1.68810 4.6 67.8 8 1.49703 4.0 71.9 9 1.28674 3.5 5.3 10 1.26364 3.4 8.7 11 1.C6464 2.9 81.6 12 .97089 2.6 84.2 13 .88086 2.4 86.6 14 .85555 2.3 88.9 15 .77580 2.1 91.0 16 .62819 1.7 92.7 17 .60739 1.6 94.3 18 .44395 1.2 95.5 19 .38138 1.0 96.6 20 .31033 .8 97.4 21 .2249? .6 99.0 22 .17704 .5 93.5 23 .15511 .4 98.9 24 .11216 .3 99.2 25 .10357 .3 99.5 26 07408 .2 99.7 2 .06516 .2 99.9 28 .015fl .0 99.9 29 .01001 .0 99.9 30 .CO788 .0 100.0 31 .00414 .0 100.0 32 .C0331 .0 100.0 33 .C0202 .0 100.0 34 .00119 .0 100.0 3 .00025 .0 100.0 ?6 .00007 .0 100.0 37 .00006 .0 100.0 VAC 6" 0‘? \3‘»3CD\]O\\fl-¥>\Nl\)-‘ _.b_s—A \NN" ._s_s_s ONU'l-b <1 I 18 1Q 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 2s 29 30 31 32 '37. 34 35 36 57 “ICVWALTT‘T‘ 6.69565 5.46766 3 . 52596 2.7759 2.25127 2.12020 1.77167 1.67231 1.59537 1.24795 1.05129 .06539 .9071? .77319 .68712 .54035 .50140 .44255 .4oo44 .31206 .29547 .2195; . 1 7089 .14015 .12760 .0861? .04902 .03965 .01334 . 00692 .00601 .00664 .00244 .00212 .0007: .oooo4 0 . Vqu. 79 “able 5-3(b) LAG 1 -"-‘-*-‘-*I\).'\.)1\)fO’xN-13~P->\n-17\-J\O4>;D (300C)IDfDOOOA-‘N‘Nh-‘fi-x] U’.D-‘1\)—1>‘~J1‘O-*F\)C7\CDO\\NU‘I ‘Ofl-P-U‘lkflfll)‘ O O O O O O 0 19.1 32.8 42.4 49.9 56.? 62.0 66.8 71.3 75.6 79-2 92.1 94.7 96.9 90.0 no a I‘JO-J 92.3 93.6 94.8 05.0 06.8 97.6 98.2 09.7 90.1 00,4 09.7 bd.e 99.9 60.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 103.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 VACMOR KOCOflmU'I-FAKNNA 10 FIGS: WALUE 5.95461 4.56502 5.40170 2.95920 2.12170 1.85964 1.63050 1.49544 1.48218 1.23012 1.15165 1.07078 .97279 .84283 .74254 .69299 .61199 . 53597 .49777 .43507 .4060? .38518 .27 ,3 .19460 .16506 .14390 .13587 .08600 .C4726 .04275 .02412 .00369 .00216 .00056 .00038 .00008 PCT 07 VAR 16.1 1 OOOOO—h—b-imaaammo-émwaqkoow O\-\]'~-O-*\.NOO-1>O\nmwkoA A—L—A—A—hu—b CU’T'. PCT moxmmhw NA 'J~1>O-*-\lN-Q-‘OO'ID-P-O‘JJ‘J4> I\)U’1=.OO\.OU‘IU‘|C1—*-*~>\)J\O-‘ 8888 8 88838118858859153188237895853891. 81 The purpose of Table 5-3 is to show how many factors are necessary to explain the variance of the data. Hair et al have suggested an arbitrary cut off when sixty percent of the variance has been explained.2 ”he SPSS default procedure is to cease factor rotations when eigenvalues fall below the one level, which is consistent with Kaiser,35 the inventor of the varimax rotation. In this study any "cut off" procedure indicates a large nunber of factors are necessary. Hair et al's process necessitates six factors, and S 03 procedures advocate twelve factors. Ecause factor 1 explains more of the variance than any other factor it is considered to be more important than any other factor. A portion of factor 1 is illustrated in Cable 5—4. r[he entire factor 1 list is in the appendix. "able 5-4 LXG 0 Factor 1 T"actor loadings > H.3l Distad's Tes-t Ratio load ing F82 . 99227 “F3 . 9821 6 T"R4 . 98208 YRS . 97058 77129 -.94864 FR30 -. 92035 2831 -. 96235 FR34 -. 63372 Stevens used a cut off of 137' or more in his factor analysis.4 Hair et a1 endorse |.5| as a cut off.5 Others contend a slid ing scale, wherein factor loadings of |.7| are extremely important, |.5 or more are important, and factor loadings of 1.3I may be significant. Cooley 'I) 2 and Iohnes have used a cut off of; l.35|.6 I‘ach factor is arranged in a row vector, and each of the financial ratios in that row vector represent the loading of that ratio on that factor. Therefore, the relation between any of the variables and any of the factors can be observed. F‘ach row vector has the relationship that :11 correlation coefficient. In Table 5-4 F92 = am because it is in the N jz: (aj i)2 = 1 where each a-- has an analogous interpretation to the first factor and it is the second variable; 1791 's loading = .05327 and was not included in this excerpt, that is its coefficient was too small . Given that 792 has a loading of .99227, we know that (£19227)2 = .96485, and 96.5 percent of 192's total variance is explained in factor 1. Table 5-4- serves another purpose. It shows that factor1 includes nine of the thirty—seven original ratios. In spite of their high loadings, those nine ratios account for only approximately twenty percent of the variance, (see Table 5-3) . "be second factor, primarily a set of four lever%e ratios, accounts for only an additional thirteen percent of the variance. A factor analysis will not successfully reduce the variable dimension in this particular application, no matter which cut off method is used. Using Fair's suggested cut off guide necessitates six factors, but six factors only reduce the dimension to thirty from the thirty-seven ratios. Using T’aiser's cut off, twelve factors, we explain eighty-four percent of the variance, but doing so requires thirty-five of the thirty-seven original ratios, using loadings 3 I..5| C. Analysis of Stevens' Factor Analysis Procedures Stevens concluded he could reduce to ten ratios, the original 83 list of twenty. However, in observing his rotated factor matrix,7 several ratios with factor loadings in excess of |.7| were omitted. T'e still had fifteen financial ratios with factor loadinqsz |.5| after his first five rotations. Though the cutoff process is quite subjective, he may have disregarded important financial ratios. .In his first factor, his factor loadings in excess of_>_ [.5| were ‘98 (.919), long term debt to market value of equity; T915 (.962), interest to cash plus marketable securities; T“P31 (.950), net working capital to sales; and T910 (.020), long term debt to total assets. T-’rcm this list he omitted T98, and thereby discarded a ratio with a loading of .819, which most analysts would consider to be extremely important. Stevens discarded his entire second factor in spite of its high factor loading scores. "There the key ratios were T92 (.890), gross profits to sales; I93 (.946), income before taxes to sales; and 7194 (.899), net incone after taxes. Instead, from the third factor he selected two of three profitability ratios though third factors are less significant than are second factors. In the third factor, the key ratios were T"R1 (.895), earnings before interest and taxes to total assets; F95 (.823) earnings before interest and taxes to sales; and F96 (.969), net income after taxes to net stockholders' equity. Of those three, he omitted F95 (.923) presunably because it had a lower factor loading. While these 1c 2d ings are high, they are still less important than the omitted variables from the second factor. Ebr activity ratios he selected 799 (.897), long term debt to stockholders equity; T914 (.974), sales to quick current assets; and 3913 (.851 ), cost of goods sold to inventory. ‘-'ost analysts consider 811 789, long term debt to equity to be a leverage ratio. 1‘t'ore puzzling though is his decision to incorporate 71714, which did not appear until his ninth factor; his cut off was six rotations. His liquidity ratios were net income to total assets (profitability ratio) and sales total assets (activity ratio). r"he two previously defined liquidity ratios, from his table3.1 on gave 78 of his dissertation were TF3241 (.880-tenth factor) , net working capital to total assets and W31 (.050 — first factor) net worldnq capital to sales, which he included in his list of leverage ratios. ”able 5-5 is a reproduction from page fifty two of Stevens' dissertation. It is his summary of factor analysis; the percent of variance by factor . r"able 5-5 Stevens' Factor - Percent Variance Table factor Percent variance Cumulative Percent 1 21.79 21.7 2 17.40 39.20 3 13.28 52.49 4 7.27 59.77 5 5.61 65.38 6 5.31 70.69 7 5.23 75.92 8 5.21 81.14 9 5.18 86.32 10 4.87 91.19 (11-19 anitted) 20 0.00 99.99 The purpose of Table 5-5 is to compare Stevens' Tactor Analysis produced percent of variance results with this researcher's, which are shown in Table 5-3(a) . Clearly it now takes more factors and ratios to use factor analysis in a financial ratio analysis of merger candidates. 85 Additionally, it now requires more factor dimensions and therefore more ratios to attain the level of cunulative variance explanations obtained by Stevens. '1‘o illustrate, r.T‘able 5-6 is a listing of factor loadings by factor for the first seven factors on my data. It was decided not to list all twelve factors, though seven only accounts for sixty—eight percent of the variance as revealed in Table 5—3( a) . 86 mvw. hmh. mrh. mmm. **Nmm. Nwm. **mcm. wow. emm. 0mm.l mmm. mam. mom. Pea. mmm. e 888 s .8me m 888 e .8988 n 829... m Spawn... AFIPV o w oesfiomom cm 28:9 mmmH mmcficmoa 888a 8: a8 8.1% 88 .8 .919 838 8888 N&¢Om. emmew. memm. $88808 sum 828 FOmmh. "meom* :88... M88... Nmmm®.l rm mm Fm om rm mm mm 8N mm 91 .m. cmsp pm3oH mum: mmzam> mpSHomLm mmo:3 chHcmoH “Sufi E; Sm mmumm .mm .mm .a Eng 6 83.8 Eofidfi* mmm—w. mmmmm. NQme. vm¢bw. Mama. Frmmo. mvvmo. mvvvd. mmfifim. Ovmvm. _ mmwmw. wmvmb. wmmmo. hmVON. momma. Oqum. waCh. dvmmo. mmm¢m. b 883 m SSS m “Sufi q “88,” m 85mm m #8th Ami: m 93 8330a 88% an 83mm Ragga you mwcfl E8 “Bump $3 99.9 $me mlm mach: oomhm. mmm¢m. mmhwm. wOOmo. hm mm Fw Om. *mm hm mm mm *Vm *mm ON 0F #3 3 *OF PNK‘O'U'LOKOP‘CD mm F bpofl 03mm 92 There are two userl discussions remaining; however: 1. To compare factor characteristics from my 197 '8 data test with those obtained by Stevens, and 2. To contrast factor analysis results with “TDA acquired results. D. Factor: 1 93 Distad—Stevens Comparisons of Results Usingg‘actor Analysis Table 5—9 1. Stevens' Factor Characteristics Compared toDistad's Factor Characteristics LAG o (t—1) SmEVETTS (1960's data) DlsmAD (1970's data) leverage Profitabil ity Profitab il ity Profitahil ity Activity Ac tiv ity leverage P/E‘ Patio Profitability Liquidity F’arket Price to Cash Per Share leverage Profitab il ity leverage Liquid ity Activity Liquid ity Profitab il ity P/E and Dividerd Payout 914 ”able 5-10 2. Final PTA and Factor Analysis Vey Patios Compared, (From Tables 5-1 and 5-6.) IAG O (t—1) Standardized Discriminant Ratio Function Factor Rotation Tactor loading VR1 +.36O 6th .76s 5 -.251 1st .090 7 -.707 6th .877 8 —.277 2nd .555 9 -.181 3nd -.959 14 -.158 5th .497 15 -.220 Ifid not appear 16 -.942 7th .?39 17 +.862 7th .007 18 -.428 6th .877 21 -.662 Did not appear 25 -. 254 4th/5th .522/ .588 27 -.130 4th .787 36 -.373 Did not appear 57 . 276 5th . 558 The key Observation from mable 5—9 is that leverage and profitability’ ratios are the most important financial variables. Activity ratios do not appear to be of import in the t-1 models. P/F ratios and dividend payout percents were of comparable levels of hnportance in spite of the time gap between the two studies, but are of greater import than indicated by Stevens. 'T‘he second discussion is to contrast results derived from a factor analysis with those derived from a.discriminant analysisrnodel. Table 5-10 uses 1970's data tests performed by Distad and are unrelated to Stevens' earlier study. From the preceding analysis we see that while "DA is of only limited significance in dimension reduction, it is clearly superior to 95 factor analysis in this application. factor analysis was unable to significantly reduce the nunber of variables. Of perhaps as much importance is the extent of contradicting results of important variables selected via discriminant functions as Opposed to the variables selected using a factor analysis, as illustrated in “able 5—10 on the preceding page. E. Replication of the Stevens liodels After studying merger activity in the Sixties, Stevens cited the need for a follow-up study in a subsequent time period to determine if the financial ratios which reflect the attractiveness of a target vary over time.8 r:"he purpose of this section is to review his study and to provide the follow—up study. He conducted two separate tests in his dissertation. “be first discriminant function was an ex post test of forty mergers. From an original twenty ratios, Steven's reduced to four, the nunber of ratios in his final model. His discriminant function was: where the coefficients have been standardized and, ("327) X1 - Net lncome/"btal Assets (W12) x2 Sal es/ Total Assets (7331) x3 T‘Tet Vbrlcing capital/sales (mo) x4 = Long Term Liabilities/“Votal Assets, and Xi’ i = 1-4 are ranked in ascending order of imlcortance.g Stevens' classification matrix was:10 96 "‘able 5-11 ”DA: Classification Vatrix. Observed Groups Actual Predicted Acquired Ton-acquired < «s > .4! < . ) Acquired (85) 33 (X11) (17) '7 (X12) = 40 lion-Acquired (52) _2_1_ (X21) (48) 12 (X22) = 9.2 54 2.6. .89. His overall classification success was 65¢. The Stevens replication conducted here was not as successful. Those results are in Table 5-12. Three separate classifications were conducted, using financial data three, two, and one year prior to the merger. Overall classification scores were 54.4, 53.4, and 52.1”: respectively, all significantly below his 65%. 97 Table 5-12 Distad's Replication of Stevens' Coefficients (Equation 5-1 ) t—5 t—2 t—1 Stevens Observed Groups (LAG 2) (IAG 1) (IAG 0) (t—1) Ratio PR7 -1.004 .599 .52? X1 = .005 W10 - .835 .805 .667 X4 = .351 FR12 - .258 -.158 «299 X2 = .934 Overall Classification Success Rate: 54.4407 53.36“? 52.05"? 65% One of the four most critical differences in the Stevens comparison is the lack of uniformity in the signs of the coefficients over time. A second difference is in the coefficients of the Stevens model. Why are the signs of the coefficients different in sign and magnitude? For example; consider sales to total assets, X2 (TR12) . As Stevens indicates: This ratio is an indication of how efficiently the assets of the firm are being employed with respect to the generation of sales. ’Ihe higher the ratio value, the greater the efficiency of the assets in producing sales. "he higher the ratio value, the greater the efficiency of the assets in producing sales. If acquired firms were systematically inefficient, with excess liquidity and under utilized assets, ratio X2 would be lowgr for the acquired group than for the non-acquired group. It is puzzling to encounter the sign and magnitude of the coefficient for his sales to total assets ratio (+ .954) . A researcher would hypothesize an absolute value somewhere near zero if the ratio was of limited significance, and would certainly hypothesize a. negative sign if a weak ratio was significant. Ratios in my updated Stevens test were 98 negative for all three years, cross—sectionally, prior to the merger, and their absolute values were not extremely large, thereby confoming more to a hypothesized coefficient. The third critical difference is the difference in the classification ratios' overall ability to properly categorize the two samples. Stevens produced a 657‘ classificaion rate, but using his ratios 1 was unable to repeat his success using data from another time period. Fbr a comparison, refer again to Table 5—12. The fourth critical difference is in misclassification costs. (he such type of misclassification appears in Stevens' classification matrix in rfable 5—11, and are summarized in Table 5-14. Tlisclassification errors in this matrix format are separated into two type of errors (X12 and X21). A Type I error, rejecting a correct hypothesis, is the incidence of acquired firms being misclassified as non-acquired firms (X12) . Stevens, using two samples of 40 firms each, correctly classified ‘35??? of the acquired firms, (55/40). Hence, Stevens' model is successful in this respect with only a 17% failure rate. P’fy attempt to replicate his model was not as successful. Refer to Table 5-14 for a comparison. (he economic effect of a Type I error is that arbitrageurs are deprived of an opportunity to achieve the risk adjusted superior returns which accrue to stockholders. A second effect of a Type I error is that managers do not perceive their firms to be likely candidates and are unable to improve the Operations of the firm sufficiently to either maximize shareholder returns or to thwart a takeover attempt. It is difficult to assess the impact of this type of error because one aspect of it is the incidence of 99 layoffs of both management and labor. Perhaps offsetting this aspect is that both managenent and labor may be shareholders, and they may be extrenely well compensated given a takeover attenpt, especially if the target is the benefactor of a bidding war between two or more potential acquirers. A third economic effect of Type I errors is that firms possibly have been acquired unwisely or that the acquirer was motivated for reasons which are not anbod ied in the four financial ratios employed by Stevens. Again, the literature is replete with the incidence of unwise acquisitions occurring in the Sixties, measured ex-post. A fourth effect of Type I errors is that firms seeking to acquire other firms for diversification benefits conclude, erroneously, that the target will not becone an acquisition and acquirers forego any of the resulting benefits. A Type II error is the second form of misclassification error. Such classification errors occur when a model suggests acceptance of a false hypothesis. In this application that event exists when the model incorrectly categorizes a merged firm as not likely to be merged, (X21) . ’lhe major Type II misclassification cost occurs to arbitrageurs. They incur opportunity costs after omitting funds to the purchase of shares of firms which were not subsequently acquired. Additionally, if the misclassified firms demonstrate the hypothesized below average performance, the arbitrageur is exposed to additional losses in the market place, resulting from falling share prices. Here, Stevens' classification success with non—acquired firms was much lower. His model failed to categorize less than half of the 40 non— acquired sample, 19./40 = 49-5”), or ()(22/X2 ). And as a result, his 100 Type II error rate here was large, 21 of the 40 (520??) firms not acquired were incorrectly classified as merger target candidates. Stevens suggested that though these firms may be candidates for acquisition, the market has not yet perceived them as such.1'5 Put, the probability that the market has not yet realized the attractiveness of the target as an acquisition is reduced given the results of my update of Stevens' test. Type II errors are shown to exist three years prior to a merger, and very little reduction of that form of misclassification is observed over time, according to my replications. T--"y results appear in Table 5-14. The effect of Type II errors in Stevens' mode " . . . raised some doubt with respect to the usefulness of the model in an Operational sense."14 *************** Recause of the larger percent of Type II errors in his model, Stevens reformulated his data into "natural" groups of firms that were merged and those that were non-acquisitions. He referred to the latter as: " . . . eligible firms not yet acquired."15 That reclassification of his data produced the following discriminant function. Again, he used the same four ratios, which unfortunately does not tell us if the discriminant function for his "natural groups" contains the "best," or optimal, set of ratios. The new discriminant function is: "natural": 2 = .531 x,, - .573 x2 + .002 x3 - .619 x);g (Tquation 5-2) , compared with his "original": Z = .005 X1, + .954 X2 + .064 X2 + .552 X4 (F‘quation 5-1). 10]. Again, X1 = Net Income/Total Assets (RR?) :2 = Sales/Total Assets (.1212) X3 = Net tbrking Capital/Sales (“R/’1) X4 = long Term liabilities/"otal Assets (Two) Using Fquation 5-2 provides results such that the coefficients for X2 and X4 are nearer their hypothesized values. The coefficient for sales to total assets, X2 (W12) , should be less than average because the firm is not prOperly utilizing its assets. The result provided from Iliuation 5-2 is much closer to the coefficient produced in my replication (in Table 5-12) . rT'he coefficient of long term liabilities to total assets, (X4, W10), should reflect lower than average debt levels as a percent of capitalization. The new classification matrix (Table 5-15) indicates an improvement in overall success. Though classification success fell to 6394 from 657’ (see Tables 5-11, 5-12), there was a reduction in the extent of Type I and II errors. 102 r“able 5-1 3 fievens' ITew Classification of Tv'erger Groups17 Actual ‘Tew Groupings Predict I‘actcr 1 Factor 2 (Likely to be (Not Likely to be Acquired) Acquired) (675) f? (‘4) Acquired ( 67) 26 ( 3'5) 15 30. Non-Acquired ( 41) 1: ( 59) §_2_ fl ii 15 16. Overall classification success is: 65% = 26/76 + 22/76 Type II errors (41¢) were much greater for Stevens as those levels occurring in my tests, shown in Table 5-14, below. Type I error levels are much greater in my replications, using his ratios, on new data. *************** 103 Tabl 8 5-1 4 Conparisons of "‘ype I and II I‘rr'or Levels Stevens Initial Study Few Classification (Table 5-11) (Table 5-13) TYPE I 1'7?! 320’ Thor (1) (7/40) (1.3/39 Pym II 5274 417?: Frror (9??) (21/40) (15/37) by 9.15033 t—3 t-2 t-1 (IAG 2) (IAG 1) (LAG 0) Type I 8.194 92??! 917’. Error (%) (189/254) (218/235) (214/235) Type II 15?“ 795 8’.” Error (%) (42/275) (152/271) (20/253) 1011 Stevens then ran a third test, generating a new discriminant function, but not restricting himself to the ratios derived fron his original test. Tran that third test the following discrim inant function was calculated: Z = .052 19+ .163 X2 -1- .079 X3 - .95? X4 - .276 Y5 (unation 5- '2’) where: X1 = Dividend Payout (W16) X2 = Net Income/Total Assets (“3.7) X3 = Net Working Capital/Total Assets (W24) x4 = Sales/Total Assets (r912) - Long rem Debt/Total Assets“? (“910) >4 U'I I It is not especially useful to compare the coefficients of this function with his two earlier versions. Pecause of the inclusion of the fifth ratio, the magnitude of the other four coefficients will be altered. However, only net income to total assets and sales to total assets of the original four ratios renain in the final discriminant function. Stevens failed to explain the different set of ratios in this model. Furthermore Stevens changed his best leverage ratio to long term debt to total assets from his original long term liabilities/total assets. His distinction between debt and liabilities is: The only items included in long term debt were actual 10% term instrument such as bonds and notes. long term liabilities include in addition, various accounting egtries such as deferred compensation, deferred taxes, etc. , No explanation is given for the change, for the effect of the change, or why the new ratio was not employed in the original version of the model. The sign of the coefficient is negative, indicating below average leverage, which is consistent with his natural grouping 105 coe ffic ient . “y efforts to replicate his third model were less successful. Use of those five ratios produced a model which was significant at the .0763 level (92.34%). In comparing coefficients: Stevens': Z = .052 X1 + .163 X2 + .079 X5 - .953 X4 - .236 X5 (Equation 5-3) Distad's Replication of Stevens: (IAG 0): Z = —.538 X1 — .417 x2 + .361 KB - .025 X4 - .665 X5 (Fmation 5-4) Again, clearly there are differences in magnitude and signs of the coefficients. Stevens indicated an overall classification rate as follows: 106 ‘9- El E1 rmpmwc was wcs 0e as am Ame J A: static; mum mam Ass V mm Aoav swaps; A s v A v V conpoalcow mommy... mflflflm “Mfla schemesasmm m.smpmss swa soaps as mass soaks H mass sac aUmpSoo< scameWwwmmmHo mco>mpm ms mm ms .mw .Iw A smv .ma A «av s>assssspaposssp<.soa_ m>ssosspp< assessmss mmmmmq figsfifisfififlmgtfi Hmwo; cmPMHSELo%mm..wco>opm w 0.. ,mam EO..®,. wcm>® 2 AOL mQOHL w“... COH wOH Hmmm F + k4 0 U C. o FF 0 o o m Tm w Home 107 Clearly, my replication of Stevens' reformulated model was unsuccessful in identifying likely merger candidates, identifying less than ten percent of firms which were merged. It also produced a low total classification score using his model,contrary to the results he obtained from his test of mergers in the 19605. IAG 1 and IAG 2 classification rates in the replications produced a 54¢ overall classification success in both time periods. In a subsequent article, Stevens introduced a fourth discriminant function from the same time period.20 In this model, Z = -.0'53 X1 + .987 X2 + .108 X3 + .111 X4 (Fquation 5—5) arranged in ascending order of importance where: X1 = Net Working Capital to Total Assets (r324) X2 = Sales/Total Assets (r812) X3 = Sales/ Total Assets (T15) X4 = Long Term Liabilities/motel Assets (H210) Only X2 and X4 appear in the discriminant functions generated in the earlier model versions of his dissertation. In comparing the coefficients of X2 and X4 fran the article and the dissertation we find: 108 "‘able 5-16 Stevens' Coefficient Comparison Original TIatural Ti nal Article “"odel "odel l'odel "odel Ratio (W: 5-1) (170‘: 5—2) (7101 5.5) (’5le 5—5) X2: Sales/Wotal Assets (32.12) .954 —.575 —.955 .98? X4: long "‘erm rebt (Liabs)/ .552 -.619 —.256 -.111 Total Assets (2910) Stevens' models tell us that sales to total assets ratios for firms being acquired are important, but there is a sharp contradiction considering coefficient signs. Only in fievens‘ natural (Equation 5-2) and final (Fquation 5-4) models are the coefficients as expected: target firms should be expected to be less efficient than those firms not considered to be as desirable for acquisition. It is possible that different ratios in the final discriminant function would account for coefficient magnitude variations, but there does not appear to be an explanation for the differing signs. Furthermore, there does not appear to be any reconciling the positive coefficient calculated for long term liabilities (or debt) to total assets. In his equation 5-3, the coefficient using long, term debt rather than long term liabilities was not materially different from his coefficient in equation 5—5. Again, I am unable to reconcile his positive coefficient (+5552) in equation 5-1. The classification matrix from the model appearing in his article is: 109 rTable 5-1'7 Stevens Vodel (Tquation 5-5) A ctual Pred icted (Pegged [a T:fon—Verged Verged (PS ) 34 (15 ) 6 = 40 ‘Ton-"eraed (45 ) E (55 ) ?_? fig 52 2‘3 = 90 Distad's Replication (LAG 0) A ctual Pred icted I‘lerged Non—”arsed ( "’ ) .fi‘ ( "5 ) "eraed (7) 16 (9'5 ) 215: 229 Non-"erged ( 6) fl (“4) 27g 22: 31 451: 482 Stevens Qistad Classification Accuracy 70¢ Type I Error 154 Type II Error 457'? 110 To summarize Stevens' endeavors, he derived four different models; the first of which (Equation 5—1), using return on assets (FY37) , total asset turnover (£0.12), net working capital as a percent of sales (W31), and long term debt as a percent of total assets (W10) produced an overall classification success rate of 657’. This first model would have produced considerably better results if the Type II error level, 52 percent error rate, could be reduced. “‘Iy three replications of his first model were less successful producing success rates in the 52-54 percent range. The extent of the Type II error levels in Stevens' first model necessitated a second model, (Fquation 5—2). His overall classi- fication success dropped slightly to 63:33 from 6557:. and his Type II error level rate fell to 4170 from 52%. r‘z‘he ratios used in his second test were those from his first model, but the regrouping by " natural" rather than by actual groups produced discriminant coefficients with conflicting signs and sharp differences in the magnitude of their absolute values. Stevens' third model (Equation 5-3) was another discriminant function of the same data; the only differences were the inclusion of an additional ratio, dividend payout (I816) and a redefinition of long term debt. In this third model long term debt disregarded various deferred liabilities including taxes and compensation. ”his third model demonstrated much higher classification success (92,71) and dramatically lower Type I (5:19) and Type II (13“?) error rates. F’y efforts to replicate this third model were not as successful. Y-‘y replication produced a 53” classification rate, and Type I (9%) and Type II (7’5) error rates. his model, when applied to my sample in a different time span could not isolate mergers, classifying only 23 of 235 firms which had already been lll acquired. Please refer to Table 5—15 for a more extensive discussion. Stevens' final model (T’quation 5-5) was constructed for a published article [125]. Using this model Stevens obtained a "Or-f classification success. He also attained Type I (1‘5“) and Type II (4555) error rates. My attempt to replicate his model were less successful generally with the exception of a lower Type II error rate(6"’-). F'y replication produced an overall classification rate of 5351’» and a high Type I error rate (93¢) . In other words, his model classified only 16 of 229 firms which had already been acquired in my sample. A more detailed discussion of his model and my replication appear in Table 5-17. It is important to emphasize that any conclusions reached as to the efficacy of Stevens' models in subsequent time periods is reduced to the limitations of my sample and replications. l'y replications indicated that his ratios, their coefficients, and his models did not demonstrate significant ex post classification success in any instance. Obviously it is necessary that his models be tested again in subsequent time periods, as well as mine, to ascertain their significance econanically and statistically. T'ore importantly, his models were also unable to predict mergers, ex ante, occurring in a subsequent time span. A more detailed discussion of that deficiency is provided in Chapter VII. F. Analysis of the Simkowitz—T-"onroe "odel At approximately the same time as the Stevens [155] study, Simkowitz and It'onroe (Sl') completed a study of firms likely to be acquired by conglcmerates [118]. Pecause the study was restricted to conglomerate acquirers it has received less attention here than that given the Stevens Study. 112 Hewever, it needs to be considered because the S” study used a dimension reduced version of an T"DA model which resulted in a set of "key" ratios unlike those derived in Stevens' reduced set of variables obtained using a factor analysis. In a subsequent article, Stevens wondered if the resulting dissimilar set of ratios was attributable to the differing dimension reduction techniques. S“ concluded that four financial ratios were most important. Listed in descending order of importance, they are: 1. low price to earning ratios, 2.‘lowwlividend payout rates, 3. lowygrowth.rates in equity, and 4. lower dollar levels of sales than their acquirer's sales levels. One of the chief differences between the SN and Stevens studies was in the importance of price to earnings per share ratios (p/e). ST concluded that lower than average p/e ratios were the most important variable in classifying a firm likely to be acquired by a conglonerate in the 19603. That is very consistent in the merger literature of that time as amotive for mergers as well as a characteristic of acquisitions. Stevens concluded otherwise in his test. His test was not confined to conglomerates, and nowhere in his fourSJC JLCUN C G R HT .UTLH ACAH Katrtnu ORRU CCCC D. R O C S E S I C PR I RU N 0r. _U Aha in R RCFJP T. LCNRR C LBIAUPE .UA PCRLL hit)? nBtI DANG Q SRN v. L IEPLNIIPLN .IT. CIIEC RTJVKRNS UUHEIOYA CCUDDODE Pnbcc .HSAE EEFF is ELEC no .0 NSA. BCEC .BD( Y£UE LN gkkLS RIRATA O ERA VCRIELNRH BYRNREO LRAEELL FFfiGGGG E , FOG..UG . T SCOTT SUPERHARKETS HOUND CCHPUTER ERY STORE PROUUCTS CO DON Imps INC «luv-“ban. ICAN LOKP - C .UDF. INC N CED NIN. .lSI CCIY Nour- .L US I.RE LK J ASAA NM RALR AEEE HHfiH .CGT A__ PRUUUCTS CORP -CL L CURP A m? b CC FCCC PERI BC? H F F "LCIR O E N A E I CR. YY.N. HHIL 177 m .. P i 0 0 C. R Z M C C D. R 0 T. Q . C S K S P C I j H C NTT O C Q x R S C N INC C C PM E N C TCTY T I P C EU RIC .c p: .N NNCS .u N .R NJMO r.n7o C N N K H I.EIUB. H E H O IREC N RN CR1 I C T M 01. D U C ECRC E OI A A C I P G WSOL. R R L SK PM H CO R 3 T N H Y R F N CdR SE A A C t ECU I P LOA E N f C O O 00 I IP+ NU G N R PIANO I LICCINOU O T C C S PIA ALI U RRPAUS U U ICU DC 0 S U NcaLSRHN 6P IT 5000 LOE G d)NNL M R E R c... EL 0 ANSLDOET RR TNS DICCTFTFN .t PJAARRRLsuc. ISCCPE C L PH EINCRT AC TCOEIR Rt AER IC NI C IOEIF RDCNRK A R R LEI BI UCCRNCI EPCLGLREOCLNO HJI ATTCCS UFN ICC P A OPORCIN N H G CAI RNHRC FIOdFIRIT .51RR AN AL HC ID CO 3 H.CIC0 SCSNR. SL H EAATO NHOE AI U EFTVINRV Y RP BPCPC H LHCCASF IX RTHLCC C AIINAPAO KYHMSE ABAC HLKEDIKRRRR. NS+ 06 ITTERNOOHET IR IOTLRR R C RRA ALCE.DN LCEFTOEOEON AR HR .TNSNOU VTNiNEdDQLCS UUnKbE 0R EEICL I AUNSSLKCACIAKEHGASYSO I CSAAOOUIN RTLSESUURRCOR YEHHH FOEE DTAGBKC V GET AIBICEC INAMPCICLUAAAhESSEAYRE 81 151 CKIE NNRNNII VON AAHCHBGNNNEDG”HNRRSUCIDNDLSSOHLNI HHR RICNNRP EEEIILN TVA EEEEEEIOOOOPAAAAAAAAACCEEIIIIOOOOU EEOA OTAAAAE. KKKKKKKLLLL LLL LLLLLLLHHHMHHMHMMHHMMHHHMMMHHH NNN.NOPPPPPJ O C A . R P U L .. .L R C C C” 6 C C P C 8 W N .. M C N E SR N C R I C P“ U 3 I L UOP I h C G N Rm L C D a NCR I C NS I 0Q NPN 0 A m CE I O S P S S C , NN CC + IRI C C NV CC I H E PL R N N .1090 Y _ ha I Ir... NH .u D C RA E 00 I HIRN A SC. 0 MC... ’RU .l AIM .r. a, C R 0N T. SC TOION HI 0 P A EN 5 SO M30 H0 C U CC C EC S RPEAC CE ERS 03R LC‘ T: E DH S as UC N L PCN. I N .41 J )LLE RNC S C STIYSS NDONII 3 0R NRSLKH R I O RSQCT SI CH C PPAEROA CIIROGA ESC AONCYCCNOU RUECQ IIDLCOPIfS. P Q CHINA 0 TI. R NCCC.CTLECFR IYEHNONLC E ECNHR I ANCAHRS C SRSPPCRTIN NS FLO D CObC.T NBPCH RSLRISIPFHDHHN CILSPC IKPICNLN\ 000 R CUR I0 REC A hC(ICSL DEUAF TOT EI A A IHSHI RIF .CILI NCNLOELuLE NCOL OE I TN C LCPP LLCSN AYHRUKCKCC OYCSSSDDC A I IRCLTCITPPRINCEHCH RSAILO 0R ALE UAO EOERODCUON +X ICAEHRRR HHO R 0 YAEUNRRO I T R HEMN NT GARLHEVRDRMNL NAUNUNOO EYI BHAAAAAA C EAEPUUNRBIOOSR RRRRE GMA N0 .N EEAHEfiNTARNIVURAIAHT NLLCK HIDDURNNN LIISCC CCUEOOEOEH LYAEC C ICUGIKSKIEGUETIUENINRL,CPL CATRNhhAIlR FSF 18.15" CClhhhT OLTLCCE ECDEVCCC FNTHORAAEAEEU HHEIILUAAAAAAEE MXH FRSSIAALLEICGLRA LCUYAEE.HIIIIOOUHAAACCCEEHHHHH IIK.LOOPTTIIIII.EEIRUU..RTCLAEEIAAAE PPPPRRR.. RRRRRRRRSSS.SSSSSSSJSSS SSS. SSSJSSSQSSS ITTJTIUJUUVJVVVJHuHN I o o w WESTERN NUCLEAR INC HHEzLABRAICR cox? HHITERCROSS sroaes INC W HILSON CERTIFItU Foqos In; NILSCN-SINCLAIR co HILSON spourrnu COOUS co YQNKERS RACENAJ Luc- _ YOC-HOO CHCCCLAT: agveaaua YOUNGSTCHN STEEL seas co NATIONAL INDS yo 180 APPENDIX II Subfile 2, Control Group, Non-acquired Firms .U S SUGAR CORP CORP NLHC Inn 1 RAF X‘sLl ADCC MEEA NFHP INC 065 CORP URGES + CHERICAL L.’ CORP LF DO SO R. U 5th 39. E ( XELR EHUU IPGd _ lhr DI E PC TOPLR S RN L R0 E OI RORN S C CC 5 LOCI AOR N SE LI E G U IS C IRLP JOE E R REI + +OSVET U RPOS ‘ BtENA 0 EU N LNRCIB SPP MSLI LI P ERR TS I0ALNA+ R00 .thA C RAIN CC AAIBN E.SA G K II. OVYRTILN SDUIT CRRtFAItANE ALFBAAHA JXER .vEEC FIT NNLEUES- IICAM “8N RAF?! «UNE NHLE 253.5. «UCOGflI‘K UCGRSNSC LUERS CUR}T CORP BUI TRON CRP vLCC A E .KILR €an NNU EYL 53F E INC INC RIG 0 0N OOPI C" N§AC C Sun IH‘I RC S UAE BBCN IHAO LCLT. LSLR AIAC HFHN NG CO INC S E 0 I C SR ”Ho-00- NSC o AU J RON 0 85C“ 11‘ D T TIILnN N253...» UVCH IRRI. ETA-I. t C B N I L C S . G P S N 0 R I H E L 03 L L C DL I Y CTI U MORD NLT Tu CAN I S 0 GA EI .80 pcnunb HFD o INS CE H LI RPSENC oCLRDERUKAN JNAUEHCBSMI TI PTRC.UR 0 AA R CA RARNMFOECFI ERAOA CSN.E KCUTCYNUINL CAESLNEtLhB LNALANRHRCC HCEAHA‘UNARE SCSRAFCACBH BRANDS INC 181 NC , _ P C R - S 0 0 E C C P C I N RCC C R L I ONN NP R T A C OS CII IR AP E S 0 0 3 N N PCRA DVD. 0 R B C C C C U 0 PI D. R F. CCRRSS SC L0 3 C N S N C 0 PI R SR ONH NOALL 0 L CC U N I D .b Cf... f m N RT IUSEO R 3915 )ECEAA C C «RI 0 . D. R C I 0 N N I DA TEIC E E1 .6 LCC NS CP P C OH R N 0 R I I.) YE c CN IR PPRTL H... LCIIO+PI ID. R TU 0 f I 03 R P N E DINNS Q. PSRIK AR ETB C RAUHTC R HI 0 E LE C TELO N S PONAITPEEPRETSRP PCNAU NN CNE DOGU ES C C L E S LILF H .IPLRRBNG RRUTROHSUAR CIPP IHEI H + oCUU HS 9. I LG I: R RP R F C PRLC CACOROCANOCCUCLC D - P CSHUCCIU RC CICPRL V PIR H I ARSTHAPT SOI CERLAPCCIC HDNCC RT. Yh RCJUEN «HI SCCRC SNROI RPRCTCIPT GODS IRE CHU P ES S E NI. AFNTO OCIOHADMLGN PNNSIOCO E ENJR ICLUXSCR L A th DANERLI Y PUACIR C HCLLREIIG IA C SC LPIICE C U0 .0... ALSNC cOAGROCCTOA LL RORCC 93M GOAI LNN MHC KA C A CC OAN R S NLG IT RN00 IIUNNLR OHC IR A NADNHH EKIUNS ARRR S LIOOR N KRI .OK DEN LIE ICHEPNCOAEE C RELE TEA EEHPYLHLSOUTLEA. EYLRRC. SA LaR “CL CISIprPCp; LSDCSUHCMHIP. W8 TEhFP Aha-5L c L..NTIR.“LR.\~CTI — "RILEELCA II YLU YYT. ISRAGUUNNTAIASMTCCM LFPCHR CHRLLHINLAIEHVARCXNAAILHPSX CL AUOA AUN AUD. NLCCUUTJHAOKEII POATIA ROAILEECIEMTCEUILEISHIOQHEEAEL BCCF CHILNB SACHJMOSBCMCNRTK AFPSSH ABHNANRILSSSJRCEADKA CHUIIT.. AA 182 L 0 A C C P N S R I c S E C N E R o C S I _ N I C SE C S I P 50.5 X .b C C L AIR N FL N CR 0 S 0R0 § E N N N C 00 Ner CID. I .30 C P E 0N0 P PM I I I N RC 0T5 NPR N. NC R I CIC R LR N 0 I T‘ ISU IE0 0 N P Y 00R 0 EOE I S 3 C mm “W0 EC R O R PSST G P CCT SHHN C ECO F E E L CC NVN SN C I O RUCN O R S LUCI T E I I b A I RLI EIE CA S C OBIE L 0 GSU ALRL L SLO RNCR R . S 5 IGN CL I C In 0 0 CP NSDCIDUHCE ER ANT TSS R LS E SPRNI I C S TEP N C R IANNRUBCNE NEE CHIS SK. E ME WLNRTER 6H EOCPANNIPHS DEC KLJIELSUIT RTCPER U LRL CV CSP HAO S A C F L RCIRTIGURCI NCTC CC I TI SCESAR ALDPOO< NI R RC UNMPCN MITPCP TOARAQOEC 0 I 0 RNAYTLE NT OAHANRNH SIN I+O E 00 RNIC TNRN GECDPMECTU SRRECHYfihMNI KLISCEC. TICI TC U I CCEAE hICC ABAICIWFN . CO 0! OC ATO EP+AA EID I+E C YTNX M4 CWMN ITRC DION C MGOLODLXEOC R EH RHSDNH. LNKHL 0L MN SEEIEW RmmET 0 SA.CR HNN S A?O.EfiECR AYDSNCK HAGOSRCEHBSCCNAOOILRwUu.EbdAS T SUOPEOOTIORC SHPRUITRAPO HEI CBC, ICECSEITILCSSCBICRNRLL TMNA HS EEBEIRCACEEI K .IELICR Cr CRRS CONULLPITTRRPBRthTSRAnCIM.3aLRW Y TMIPRXMRNRVNENC NEFGMCBNETG IAI NROOULHLNACOEUAOAECACITTWH;PE§CENEWAOUOOEAAICCOHIH OFFIETAE RBSU AB SVAABINNNRTHCHKAEN357 I KIK YCORPRCMCCDIABIMCSACMSTI . CONP OF AMERICA ECTRIC CO 183 S D N I D E L L 0 RC TN NI P C C R CR N O OUIOCO NMC C C A. L H CHGL AN ITAIEEA RLT. VGEF EAYGNNP MEACIUQ AHMSSSI fl PR RC 0AM C.E LT COS NNY RIS T CCN LIO ERI TT 00A PIEC RDLI OAEN CR U AH TETM STIC ETHC TES .YUH €3.50 RFTN .AAY LMLTHJM RAL STGNRL-CORP CO ‘15 CORP E K h G SON (E.F.) URHO P RC FCNP m 0 XTC EE XPNS RCIR. P R U C S C I N 0? RR W0 5 C T E 7 NC LRD EI EET HRO ILPUTC {F R C 100 EC TCC LF C EM.J EYH REC RN SE OI LET BL TEHbLH CAOOUMVT NLE AC AAACEIPSDBE Ex} iNC-CL a '4E3TCN CCRPfi FDI INC CORP fiExECUTIVE INDUSTRIES SHITH (5.0.) TRH INC UPMAN CORP GR ELL INTL CORP ROCKH C 30 N “C I RC 3 TI E bFS I UIC R P UTIPPT R PNNSRRS c RIEYCOU c C IHCCD COOP NCK 55.x INC LA AE II USRRR Y H KEETU EKS .LhHCQ— LN.“ INSEA Lfiu TJFSH T56 N 0 H H LP S 55 N U 0 N 3 TL 0 I C SI EP 5 I H H C E (P5 M NR+T TB E O S N INRE I0 “NOT E0 ,7 R901 P CLCLL CICS FNIC TECR RSNR tL [T Y ROT S SH TPUYIIT E NSGS ESIC E UTCSRC AH dOUJN CHILI I D IUD 5 GS CHCIRC DIR RONOFDCS EDIE? MUTE EIT TCISIN NHNLE SLCASHN UC S DIED IR? EEC ADC—H E UEDYfl LR LCF RTE CPS TSL DRNT ECT N 50 L80 IGLEE NAA DY R R NRE AYO AT [ER INC? ICI ETNOhE EAN PB Rd A ARA CT RE HTA OSNSURNNd A ISDCBHN:WSI . A0, . ACY FEE 60 a I ;MMWSSu%SLTBRNIhT.TET MFA SfiLNSGLALLAE CCI FLS HLd AHIAIICEtEEMUAON ALO 0U” (HSH HRGLYDSE-PRU.TA3 CGH 181! 0 LC HA ERS TUA SIC YA SNN 0 SCI nEN GTUC A N ACNI IIY LL CKR USCC LNCC OCRI CCBN 3 CE R COCI HC IC IR PE R EIE LOTCCLH *ECCIIIC E VIP fEL RU CE E C 631 SDI IAV+ NR LGR CAT ES ILC CSSAOLKE II C BCL ROC UOE TNIE PR CILL N ELBL IOI LLUI R S EIPV UEN . $5060 3531 ShC NflkU.SfiS COCO IQI III HON NSO TCC 5N5 ROI TCE GEM HL BEL NGI MIR NLE cRM EH RIO 53C ERA HIT“ ANC‘ 0 cC C N #0 C I N C 0 N II SN C I S T EI EEUS R 1 R R CR 03 o .t CO <5§u.t u L NT HC I . LOIS ET R F IC I0) TF‘ H pU RR. SR .OOL IBS UOH K TA P o DCI CHSV RL N,R IU. NE( ITO HHAR CS . RH CC.ELSSC AfiL flIVP RCCNOHC HEAUCflLCLC 0 CKSS CGGKSKN NFIF AAHO .Vlh..\fK RNNC CBUH BHST C N I N C CPE C NRK ICC SS CI RES 5 H EXT C EC HO NtR IIKNCCIHUD OSR NN TE CR 8 IIS II NBRH .NR I J RCSOBRFN 0.5 IEH U «3 AURANIS INC INNS RUG STORES NH E REC E SRERVURS FS SR5 SCNA 30 SIS INNZfl<fi E TCYCKL US Ih kKIRhSC R5?NCVU.IPY HRBE EH Rfifi ICCKRLC FKP INC P P R R C C C CC PO P NE RC RNII 0 00 4 Ct CIPT P SR3 L)RCCO 5006806 NPCR KR PG. CLNI RIJT TAP CT(SH£BN CL U N E NNR S I AT TIT EG SSRS NLRS.HRR «any rxnnr; GCHU FHF A K I PB N R A CLP L PP CTRLT)RR C ACAaooa N LNCN CCC I N P. W P CINS RNLE SR NFRE C(TB EU I ER C A RC LHAN PM? A SAIH GR EPHN KFUS DOALRSI NTOKKLCN 0C3 ANSN H I CNN BE QU NLV A0 C+8 LCC ICC C NIIRES S ILS“ ANREUEI TANG NUCSRCH NNEI SIR AOZN IIHCEEI LII SSTNVMS DTTMRRRUNEMR IflICIIICELCI HNCD FFSICCF. ERATION 185 S C N P N I R I E 0 n!! F C GCNRI 0 om.tEL LC DVD" A TIAS IT SLC E CN n$§CFE nu .LUACY .AHCOS .0 NTNNA§0L ISIYC CP FE E E M VRR .fFSCC TNE IN (418’ ELI?! E BoF N “NECILCE AWILAEM NC R INN EIEEANIR CRNThCBE LEITTLMV OHAIECCC TAPNACCG INDEPENCENT LIFE * ACCIUENT LAMAR LIFE coap mfi + ACCIDENT PRovzogpt LIFE P U 0 R G L A Y 0 N o C 0 N CP P I? O Ro R TRP +0 0 AOR CR C NCCK) E R CC.HK L EL ABPN T STARL LA NPP FNIEBKCB IRR RICH NO P CO 0 NRfANQRLCC C55 RALCC ANNNFRL RAN ECILOI.E ENC FIFOC IR CRLACEATI LEANRLN RNLR SMNI‘AAUHAEO UACLCHC ACCH S R E H OT RS C P IT TV N A SL N AP R ERVSI NU G V NR EC E N+IOY TR L I TT NC E G SLCI T SYT ERNAS ETHAV INR T IL TN+ 0 C RAN I 25 SI TEE GTz$HRV SR5 LTALEET U AML VTS SATAN NSI NCU.OL* To fICRIA A 3 RI TUN R N LET UTATEEA LHCRTUHNTNC LHPVOZEAE INC—UII FKN.TSICPLR ANN.SSL MoE HAOUNAERONM sac INSPCOA "I7fijiflfifl'flfll‘ifliflfifl'lmfl'flmflr