RETURNENG NATEQZALS: I}V1ESI.J Place in book drop to LJBRARJES remove this checkout from ‘uunzyuu-L. your record. fifl§§ will be charged if book is returned after the date stamped be1ow. I . W. Jim 18 “1999 CLASSICAL COMPARATIVE COST THEORY: TIME SERIES AND CROSS-SECTIONAL EVIDENCE FOR THE UNITED STATES. JAPAN. AND EUROPE by Andrew Soiocha A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements For the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics I985 'l '7') V gxgcaxux ABSTRACT CLASSICAL COHPARATIVE COST THEORY: TIME SERIES AND CROSS-SECTIONAL EVIDENCE FOR THE UNITED STATES. JAPAN. AND EUROPE by Andrew Solocha The purpose of this dissertation was to investigate the comparative cost advantage of manufacturing industries in the United States. Japan. and Europe between 1967 and l980. Since it was not possible to derive accurately all the costs of production. the internal ranking of industries by comparative advantage was approximated using the inverse of unit labor cost and its components. labor productivity and labor compensation. The results for 1967 and 1980 indicated that the United States held a comparative advantage. as approximated by unit labor costs. in the Following industries: agricultural manufacturing. paper, nonferrous metals. publishing, industrial chemicals. plastics. office and computing equipment. and professional goods. It held a comparative disadvantage in traditional low technology products, wood products. furniture. pottery. glass. rubber. iron and steel. and most transport equipment. The three major industries in the U.S. economy which experienced a reduction in international competition between 1967 and 1980 were iron and steel. transport. and rubber. It *was seen that these significantly increased their unit labor costs relative to other manufactures. causing them to fall sharply in the internal ranking. This was reflected in the large trade deficits they incurred. In contrast. the iron and steel. transport and rubber industries in Japan and Germany were able to maintain their internal ranking. In 1967 and 1980. Japan held a comparative advantage in glass. iron and steel. nonferrous metals. transport equipment. and industrial chemicals: a comparative disadvantage in tobacco. food products. traditionally low technology products. and professional goods. Japan's comparative advantage remained relatively stable between I967 and 1980. In 1980. Germany held a comparative advantage in tobacco. food products. wood products. pottery. and professional goods; a comparative disadvantage in paper. nonferrous products. metal products. rubber. industrial chemicals. and machinery. Italy held a comparative advantage in leather. forest products. and pottery. It displayed a comparative disadvantage in tobacco. nonferrous metals. rubber. plastics. and electrical machinery. Great Britain held a comparative advantage in industrial chemicals. plastics. tobacco. printing. and other nonmetal products. Its comparative disadvantage lay in wearing apparel. furniture. pottery and china. iron and steel. and transport equipment. To Janet and Anya ii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The completion of this study depended on the assistance and cooperation of many people. First. I would like to thank my wife for her patience and encouragement. When writing a disseration. patience is certainly a scarce commodity. Second. I would like to thank my family for their support (in more ways than one) throughout my graduate studies. I am deeply appreciative of the guidance and encouragement which I recieved from my Dissertation Advisor. Professor Mordechai E. Kreinin. His attention to difficult questions and prompt reading of the materials made the disseration easier to complete. Many thanks go out to the Economics Department for their helpful suggestions and the use of the micro computers. I valued the help from the fine librarians at M.S.U.. who were instrumental in my research. Finally. I must thank Elizabeth Johnston for editing this work. although I am fully responsible for the errors which may remain. Although it appears to be our comparative disadvantage. let there be peace on earth! CHAPTER ONE - TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION 00..........OOOOOOOOOOOIOOOOOO. TWO/K THE CLASSICAL COMPARATIVE COST THEORY . ..... THREE - FOUR - A. ,B. C. D. E. F. G. H. I. H. The Ricardian Model ........ ......... .... Limits to the Terms of Trade ............ Introduction of Money ................... Limits to a Sustainable Exchange Rate ... More Than Two Goods ..................... Unit Labor Costs ........................ Transportation Costs ..... ............... Incomplete Specialization and Variable Costs of Production ..................... Ricardian vs. Heckscher-Ohlin Models .... Conclusion .............................. REVIEW OF THE EMPIRICAL LITERATURE ......... A. B. C. D. E. F. G. H. MacDougall's Original Formulation ....... Tests of the Comparative Cost Theory .... Additional Tests for Other Pairs of Countries ..... ......... ............. Evaluation of the MacDougall Approach ... Extension of the MacDougall Approach .... Justification of Labor Costs ............ Comparative Cost Theory Reformulated ....... .................. ... Summary ................................. DISAGREGGATED-CROSS SECTIONAL EVIDENCE FOR THE UNITED STATES ..........OOOOOCOOOOOOOOOO A. B. C. D. E. F. G. Data ....... ... ........ . ..... . ...... ..... The Models ........................ ...... Analysis of U.S. Manufacturing Industries .............................. Low Technology Industries ............... Medium Technology Industries ............ High Technology Indutries ............... Conclusion ............... ........ ....... iv PAGE I 6 30 30 33 39 42 45 49 SI 53 57 58 64 66 66 72 75 CHAPTER PAGE FIVE - CROSS-SECTIONAL AND TIME SERIES EVIDENCE FOR THE UNITED STATES. JAPAN. AND EUROPE ... 77 A. Data .................................... 78 B. The Cross-Sectional Models .............. 80 C. Time Series Evidence for the United States ........................... 82 D. Pooling and Time Effects .... ............ 85 E. Conclusion .... ......... . ................ 89 SIX - ANALYSIS OF INDUSTRIES ..... ................ 95 A. Agricultural Manufacturing .............. 95 B. Traditional Low Technology Industries ... 97 C. Forest Products ......................... 98 D. Nonmetal Products ....................... 100 E. Medium Technology Industries .. .......... 101 F. Iron and Steel ..................... ..... 102 G O Nonferrous Meta I s O I O O I O O O O O O O O O O I O O O O O O 103 H. Metal Products ............ . ..... ........ 104 I. Rubber Products ......................... 105 J. Transport Equipment ....... . ............. 106 K. Publishing ..................... . ........ 107 L. Energy .................................. 107 M. High Technology Industries .............. 108 N. Industrial Chemicals ........ ............ 108 O. Other Chemicals ....... ....... ........... 109 P. Plastics ........ . ....................... 110 0. Machinery ............................... 111 R. Electrical Machinery .. ....... ........... 112 S. Professional Goods ... ......... . ..... .... 112 T. Summary ...................... ...... ..... 113 SEVEN - CONCLUSION ................................. 117 APPENDIX A ............ ........ ... ...... ... ........... 124 APPENDIX B ........ ........ ...... ........ ..... ....... . 139 APPENDIX C .............. . ............................ 158 BIBLIOGRAPHY ... ...................................... I64 LIST OF TABLES TABLE PAGE 2.1 Introduction of a Multicommodity Framework .................................... 15 4.1 Unit Labor Costs and Net Trade Positions Of U.S. IndUStrIes’ 1967 and 1980 cease-coo... 60 4.2 OLS Results from the Cross-Sectional Data .... 65 5.1 U.S. Unit Labor Costs and Trade Positions. 1967 and 1980 ..................... 90 5.2 Japanese Unit Labor Costs and Trade Positions. 1967 and 1980 ................ ..... 91 5.3 German Unit Labor Costs and Trade Positions. 1967 and 1980 ........ ...... . ...... 92 5.4 U.K. and Italian Unit Labor Costs and Trade pOSItIonSFOr1980.........................o. 93 vi LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE PAGE 2.1 Unit-Value Isoquant ............ ........ ...... 24 2.2 Factor Endowments and Factor Prices .... ...... 25 5.1 Correlation without Time Effects .... ......... 86 5.2 Correlation with Time Effects ................ 86 vii CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION The main objective of this dissertation is to investigate the comparative advantage of manufacturing industries in the United States. Japan. and Europe during the period 1967 to 1980. A nation’s ranking of industries by comparative advantage can be obtained from the inverse of the production costs. Since it is difficult. if not impossible, to derive accurately the actual costs of production. unit labor costs are used as an approximation. Most previous studies comparing unit labor cost and its components. labor productivity and labor compensation. across countries have limited their scope to one industry at a given time. The problem with this approach is that a country's labor compensation is expressed in a domestic currency and must be converted to a common currency for comparison by employing exchange rates. However. these are often managed by central banks and deviate from their long— run equilibriums. causing the analysis to be invalid. To correct for these distortions. an approach developed by Kreinin (1981. 1982. 1984. 1985) was extended to encompass “the performance of unit labor costs in each industry v-elative to the national manufacturing average. Therefore. c:omparative cost advantages "are embedded in the total economy”. shifting the focus to relative rather than absolute unit labor costs (Kreinin. 1984. p. 42). An important objective of this dissertation is to construct internal rankings of industries approximating a country"s comparative advantage at different times. 1967 and 1980. within each country. The exchange rate between the countries separates the internal rankings into export industries. nontraded goods. and import-competing industries. The performance of unit labor costs is analyzed to explain shifts in the rankings over time. Comparative advantage plays an important role in determining a country's trade flows. In light of the large UzS. current account deficits recently registered. industries which lose their comparative advantage face severe international competition and often seek trade restrictions. Since factors affecting a country's comparative advantage can have important policy implications. close examination of the performance of relative unit labor costs is required. Chapter II develops the theoretical foundations of the comparative cost theory. beginning with the Ricardian hypothesis. Money wages. a multigood framework. transportation costs. incomplete specialization. and variable costs of production are incorporated inlorder to construct a more realistic model. These additional factors provide an added dimension to the theory without adversely affecting the results derived from the simple Ricardian hypothesis. Differences and similarities between the comparative cost theory and the He'ckscher-Ohl in model are also examined. and anleffort is made to reconcile the two theories. The empirical literature which tests the Ricardian hypothesis. beginning with the study by MacDougall. is reviewed in Chapter III. Challenges to the Ricardian hypothesis by Bhagwati. Kreinin. and Stern as well aa supporting evidence for it by Daly and Stryker are presented. Related material by Kreinin which does not directly test the Ricardian hypothesis but which is based on comparative cost theory is also reviewed in this chapter. Chapter IV investigates the effect of unit labor costs on the trade flows of 139 U.S. manufacturing industries categorized by the Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) system at the two-. three-. and four- digit level for 1967 and 1980. The first part develops an internal ranking for these years and formulates a cross-sectional model determining the effect of unit labor costs on trade performance. The second part arranges the industries into low. medium. and high technology categories and analyzes the performance of their unit labor cost and its components. Cross-sectional and time series evidence for the United States. Japan. Germany. the United Kingdom. and Italy is examined in Chapter V. A ranking of 28 manufacturing industries. classified by International Standard Industrial Classification (1510). is constructed for 1967 and 1980. and a cross-sectional model is developed to determine the effect of differential unit labor costs on trade performance. The second part analyzes time series data for individual industries to determine the effect of changes in labor productivity'and compensation on the trade performance of individual industries. In addition..all time series and cross-sectional data combined with dummy variables are "pooled” into one equation to remove the biases of trade discrimination and exchange rate changes over time on trade performance.l Chapter VI integrates the statistical analysis of the previous chapter and examines the performance of unit labor costs and trade flows of individual industries. The industries are grouped into low. medium. and high technology categories. consistent with Chapter IV. as a basis for analysis. The final chapter summarizes the empirical findings of the dissertation and offers a broader interpretation of the main findings with regawd to methodology and economic policy. Eggtngtes IThe ”pooling” or panel data models are based on models from Kmenta (1972) and Judge et al. (1980). CHAPTER II THE CLASSICAL COMPARATIVE COST THEORY This chapter develops the theoretical foundations of the classical comparative cost model for ranking industries by unit labor costs. The examination begins with the Ricardian hypothesis. the restrictive assumptions of which are relaxed by introducing money wages. a multicommodity framework. transportation costs. and incomplete specialization. In addition. similarities and differences between the classical comparative cost model and the Heckscher-Ohlin theory are highlighted. Within this framework. comparative cost theory attempts tolanswer the fol lowing three questions: 1. what is the basis for trade. and what goods should a country export and import? 2. On what terms are the traded goods exchanged? 3. Should disturbances occur in the trade patterns. what forces will bring about an adjustment? This chapter wi l l concentrate on question 1. although the other two questions will receive minor consideration. The pure theory of international trade differs structurally from positive theories in the kinds of questions asked rather than in the kinds of assumptions made. As Viner (1937. p. 437) has stated. ”the classical theory of international trade was formulated primarily with a view to its providing guidance on«questions of national policy mu. Recognition of its welfare analysis orientation is essential to the understanding and the appraisal of the classical doctrine." Thus. a clear understanding of comparative cost theory is important in formulating policy fOr industries concerned with international competition. The Riggrdign Mgggl The first clear statement of the comparative cost theory was developed by David Ricardo.l TheRicardian model assumes: 1. Two countries and two commodities. 2. One factor of production - homogeneous labor.‘2 3. Labor is completely'mobile within a country» and all occupations pay the same wage rate. 4. Labor is immobile between countries. so that factor endowments cannot change. 5. Cormodities move freely between countries without transportation costs. 6. The average productivity of labor is different in the two countries. 7. Constant unit labor costs. Ricardo assumedthat one of the two countries could produce both goods using less labor. thus having an absolute advantage in both goods. In his example. England is able to produce a unit of cloth by employing 100 hours of labor. or to produce a unit of wine by employing 120 hours of labor. Portugal is able to produce a unit of cloth by employing 90 hours of labor. or to produce a unit of wine by employing 80 hours of labor. Portugal is more efficient than England in the production of both goods since Portugal can produce each good with less labor than England. One English worker is worth 90/100 of a Portuguese worker in the production of cloth. and 80/120 of a Portuguese worker in the production of wine..Although English workers are less efficient than their Portuguese counterparts in the production of both goods. England's degree of lower efficiency is smaller in the production of cloth. Alternatively. Portugal's degree of superiority is greater in the production of wine. Thus as Ricardo has pointed out. although Portugal has an absolute advantage in the production of both goods. Portugal has a comparative advantage in the production of wine. while England has a comparative advantage in the production of cloth. The degree of comparative advantage can be summarized in the following inequalities: 90/100 > 80/120 (comparing the same commodity in different countries). or 90/80 > 100/120 (comparing different commodities in the same country). Limits :9 the Terms 9f Trggg Starting from autarky. each country can increase the production of one commodity only by switching some labor from the production of the other commodity. 3 The cost of cloth is the amount of wine that can be produced by the labor necessary to produce an additional unit of cloth. In the Ricardian example. a domestic exchange ratio (relative price) in terms of relative costs will be established in England of 1 unit of wine for 1.2 units of cloth. and in Portugal of 1 unit of wine for 0.88 units of cloth. These domestic cost ratios define the limits to the terms of trade. Taking account of the domestic exchange ratios. it would be profitable for Portugal to engage in international trade if 1 unit of wine could be exchanged for more than 0.88 units of cloth. For England to profit. less than 1.2 units of cloth must be exchanged for 1 unit of wine. Thus. the limits to mutually'beneficial trade must lie between (L88 and 1.2 units of cloth for 1 unit of wine. The domestic cost ratios of the two commodities in the two countries determine the limits to mutually beneficial trade (Kreinin. 1983). within these limits. each country should specialize in the production of the commodity in which it has a comparative advantage and obtain the other commodity through international trade. The classical comparative cost theory states that once free trade is establ ished. the terms of trade wi l I settle within these limits set by comparative costs. Both Mill and Marshall concluded that. within these limits. the forcesof reciprocal demand would determine the equilibrium terms of trade. Thus. the burden of adjustment to a change in tastes would fall primarily on changes in relative prices withlonly secondary effects on responses in supply. 4 I0 W The first significant expansion of the Ricardian model was the introduction of money wages by Taussig (1927). He elaborated on the three types of situations: absolute cost. equal cost. and comparative cost. The Ricardo-Mi ll model is easily elaborated in money terms since labor is assumed to be the only input and the only requirement is the money wage rate. As did the earlier writers. Taussig uses two countries and two products. The equal cost situation is 31/32 - PI/bz or al/bI a az/bz. where: a. - labor cost of one unit of good A in country 1: a2 a labor cost of one unit of good A in country II: b. a labor cost of one unit of good 8 in country I: and b2 2 labor cost of one unit of good 8 in country II. Since the cost ratios are the same. the domestic terms of trade are the same in both countries. thus providing no basis for trade. when the condition 31/32 < 1 < PI/bz holds. the principle of absolute cost advantage is displayed. With a. < a2 and b. > b2. country I has an advantage in product A. while country 11 has an advantage in product 8. If there is to be trade between the two countries. a1 ' ”I < a2 ' H2 and b1 ' H. > b2 * H2. The nelative wage ratio. w,/w2. can thus fluctuate within the limits set by thelmoney costs of the products. but not including w,/w2 - 32/31 or Nl/HZIBZ/bl. If one country is superior in both commodities. but by different proportions (a./a2 < bl/PZ <1). then we satisfy the comparative costs principle. In order for country I to II export product A. a. * H. < a2 * H2. therefore. 1 > a!/a2 < 142/141. as with the absolute costs advantage example. This allows the wages to fluctuate within limits and still permit trade. For country II to export product 8. b1 * ”I > b2 '1 H2. and by cross-multiplying. the result is 1 > b‘lbz > HZ/Hl. cu- 1 > HZ/H.. Hl/HZ > 1. Thus. the wage ratein country I. which may be considered the technologically superior country. must be higher than in country 11 if there is to be bilateral trading. The proportion of wages. wl/wz. must be at least as high as the ratio bz/b1. but no higher than aZ/a1. Hhen NZ > H‘. a disequilibrium condition occurs. and one country is cheaper. in money terms. in the production of both goods and thus exports both. To correct for this situation. the classical economists relied on Hume's specie- flow theory as an equilibrating device. Since country I will be exporting more because of the wage differential. it will be acquiring more foreign currency and gold. The increase in the country’s monetary base will increase its money supply and drive up wages and prices. At the same time. country 11 will lose its currency and gold. thus contracting its money supply. This will drive down wages and prices until a! ' H. a a2 ' H2: after this process of adjustment. normal trade conditions would be restored. while the choice of the money wage is arbitrary. the ratio of money wages between the two countries lies between an upper and lower limit. as explained above. Only the choice within these limits is arbitrary. The exact ratio is IZ determined by relative demand conditions. subject to the constraint that total value of exports must equal the total value of imports. In examining the relationship between absolute advantage and wage rates. Taussig finds that "those countries have high money wages whose exported conmodities command a good price in the world's markets". (Angel. p. 105). Following Senior and Mill. Taussig makes the range of money incomes dependent on the terms of international demand and the relative productivity of labor. In addition. competitive markets are assumed in order for the marginal productivity of labor to equal the wage rate. Within this framework. the exporting industries in each country are the primary determinant in setting the general rate of money incomes and wages. But the exporting industries set only nominal wages and not real wages. Becauselof labor mobility. the money wage rate set by the exporting industriesiwill become. under perfect competition. the rul ing wage rate in the country at large (nonexporting as well). In nonexporting industries. prices will vary with changes in wages and incomes. as in the exporting industries. but import prices will not reflect these changes. Because of international trade. incomes would rise. leading to lower real prices of imports. imit ustai able Exch n e Rate The limits to the exchange ratio can be derived from the limits to the commodity terms of trade.5 The latter is I3 expressed as an upper and lower 1 imit where mutual 1y beneficial trade occurs. If both commodities in each country are assigned prices in their own domestic currency. the limits to the commodity terms of trade are converted into the limits to a sustainable exchange rate. Within the limits specified. the precise exchange rate is determined by reciprocal demand subject to the balance- of-payments equilibrium. If the exchange rate were outside these limits. one country could undersell the other in both commodities. This would lead to an external imbalance which would require an exchange rate adjustment. Thus. the exchange rate must reflect the cost/price relationship between the two countries. More Than Two 5 Frank Graham (1923) employed the classical model and made it more realistic by incorporating a multicommodity and multicountry framework. This section will discuss Graham's contribution to trade theory in a multicommodity framework. Graham. in the classical tradition. dealt with a single input -labor- and constant costs of production. He felt. however. that concentration on two countries and two commodities severely limited the scope of the Ricardian analysis. Thus he states that ”the classical theory of international values seems to be open to grave objections which. whi le they do not subvert its foundations. nevertheless call for a substantial modification of its conclusions”. (1923. 99. 54-5). Within a Ricardian two- I4 country. two-conmodity model. adjustments in international demand are not found in changes in production (supply). Instead the adjustment process is a reciprocal demand phenomenon. reflected by changes in trade volumes and the terms of trade. Graham's emphasis. in contrast. is directed toward changes in supply. involving shifting of productive resources and altering the composition of trade. With additional countries and comnodities. adjustments to changes in demand incorporate shifts in production. along with the possibility of a change in commodity composition. These shifts in output and alterations in trade COMpOSItIOfl and direction would tend to minimize the changes in the terms of trade and thus are a long-run phenomenon. In a rigorous fashion. let the number of units of labor-cost needed to produce a unit of the goods A. B. ..... F in country I be denoted by 31' b‘.u.. f1 and a2. b2.....f2 in country 11. If R is the exchange rate. then (a, " W1 " R) < (a2 ' W2) holds for any commodity A that country I exports. A good will be exported only if its supply price (money cost) is lower than in the foreign country. For any comnodity B that is inported by country I. the condition (b. " W. " R) > (b2 ' W2) holds. Then al/az < [Hz/(W! " R)]. where WZ/(W. ' R) is the ratio of money wages. Thus. 51/32 < b‘/bz means that country I enjoys a comparative advantage over country 11 in production of commodity A. We can then arrange the various goods in the 15 order of comparative advantage of country 1 over country 11 in goods A. B. C. D. and F in the fol lowing way: 31/52 < Pl/Pz < cllcz < d1/d2 < e‘lez < f‘lfz. We can then draw a line dividing the commodities which country I exports from those it imports by the quotient "2/("1 ' R0. To determine the exact position of the dividing line. we>must introduce reciprocal demand. subject to the balance-of-payments constraint. This principle is illustrated in Table 2.1. For trade to be possible. country 11 will export product A. and country I will export product F. At least three of the remaining four products could also be traded. depending on the ratio of money wages. W2/(W‘i‘R). If Wz/(WI’R) :- 1.2 is chosen. country 11 will export products A and 8. since in country I compared to country II. the input cost of these goods is proportionally greater than the proportion of the money wage ratio. Wz/(Wl'R). The money cost of product C is equal in both countries. and thus this product wi l i not be traded. With the same analysis. country I wi l I export products D. E. and F. Table 2.1. Introduction of a Multiconmodity Framework Labor Cost Per Unit Goods Country 1 Country 11 1/11 A 14 10 1.4 B 13 10 1.3 C 12 10 1.2 D 11 10 1.1 E 10 10 1.0 F 9 10 0.9 I6 Since product C wi l i be produced by both countries in order for there to be a balance in trade. the total money value of country 11's exports of A and 8 must equal the total value of its imports in products 0. E. and F from country I. If this state of equilibrium is upset by a shift in demand in country I1 away from its domestic goods (A.B.C) to foreign goods (D.E.F.). a disequilibrium in the balance of payments will occur. To finance these additional imports. country 11 must export an apprOpriate amount of product C. Since full employment of a constant amount of labor is assumed. there must be a reduced consumption of goods A. B. and C in country 11 to supply additional exports. In moving from the initial to the new equilibrium. there does not have to be any change in the production of any of the six products. The entire adjustment process could consist of country 11 consuming only a portion of product C and exporting the rest. meanwhile importing more of products 0. E. and F. Throughout this process of adjustment. all prices and the terms of trade would remain unchanged. If the terms of trade were to move against a country because of excessive exports of one commodity. it would export other commodities in which its comparative advantage was less and stop the adverse movement of the terms of trade. Graham viewed the terms of trade as normal ly equal to the cost ratio in one of the countries. with at least one commodity (intermediate) produced in common by more than one I7 country. This intermediate commodity could serve as a link between the two countries' cost structures. In a three- commodity. twp-country example. each country could produce the commodity in which it had the greatest comparative advantage as well as the intermediate commodity. Labor costs in each country would then link the price of the intermediate commodity to each of the other two commodities. A change in world demand would then cause a reallocation of labor in each country between the two goods it produces without any change in the terms of trade. Although the multicommodity framework was first designed for comparing the cost ratios of producing the same commodity between different countries. Viner (1937) and Takayama (1972) pointed out that comparing the cost ratios of different commodities within the same country produces the identical pattern of comparative advantage. This was illustrated in the first Ricardian example. 6 Thus. it is possible to obtain an internal ranking of all industries by their cost ratios within each individual country. yielding a ranking by comparative advantage. nit r Co t All commodities produced by a country can be ranked internally in the order of their domestic costs of production. 7 These are defined as the ratio of total compensation per unit of input to productivity per unit of input. Each country exports the commodities in which its comparative advantage in terms of production costs is 18 greatest and imports those commodities which rank lowest (highest production costs). The cutoff point between what is exported and imported depends on reciprocal demand considerations subject to the balance-of—payments equilibrium. This ranking system can have important implications for economic policy; If an industry"s costs of production are high relative to other industries. the industry’would be ranked low in terms of comparative advantage. For an industry to improve its ranking by comparative advantage. it must reduce factor compensation and improve factor productivity. Although there are many factors of production. a ranking of industries based on labor costs of production is important. Takayama (1972) states that if fixed coefficients of production areiassumed. comparative labor costs can be meaningful even in a multifactor model. Since all factors are used in fixed proportions. they can be represented by only one factor. labor. Thus. a fixed coefficients production function can be represented by a labor theory of value. The conditions under which a fixed coefficients production function and a labor theory of value display the same properties were first developed by Samuelson (1951). These conditions. which hold true even if each industry has a choice of several methods of production are as fol lows: 1. All methods available to any one industry have only one and the same output (the product of that industry). I9 2. All methods in the technology have among their inputs one and only one scarce primary commodity (labor). drawn in from the outside. and this commodity is the same for all methods and industries. An elementary exposition presented by Koopmans (1953) states that any efficient nonnegative bill of goods (net outputs) can be sustained by only one price constel lation (by one ray of prices ka. kp2..... kpn. where k > 0). Given this price constellation. even though many processes of production may be available to each firm or industry. only one such process will actually be used.Thus. the only costs that need to be considered within this framework are labor costs. Transggrtgtion Costs The introduction of transportation costs can lead to a third class of goods. nontraded goods. which enter only into domestic trade. To obtain the conditions for nontraded goods. ‘51:12 is denoted to represent the real cost in units of labor for transporting commodity A from country 1 to country'II and at21 for transportation from country 11 to country I. If the country exporting the commodity pays the cost of transportation. commodity'A will be exported only if (a. + atlzvaz < WZ/(Wl ' R) and imported if 31/(32 + at21) < WZ/(Wl ' R). But if W2/(W‘ ' R) lies between (a. + at12)/32 and (a, + at12)/a2 such that a./(a2 + at21) < WZ/(W‘ ' R) < (a1 + at12)/°2' commodity A will not be exported or imported unless the difference in its cost of 20 production between the two countries exceeds the cost of transporting it from one to the other. The export performance of a country now depends on its comparative costs of production and its transportation costs. This would cause the international division of labor to be carried out to a lesser degree than with zero transportation costs. Incgmglete Specialization and Variable Cgsts gf’Pnguction Classical theory held that partial specialization could not exist. As Mill (1909. p. 589) stated. "cost of carriage has one effect more. But for it every commodity would (if trade be supposed free) be either regularly imported or regularly exported. A country would make nothing for itself which it did not also make for other countries.” Even if no transportation costs and constant costs are assumed. it is possible that only one country would specialize completely. while the other country produces both commodities. As Graham has pointed out. this would occur when one country was economically small and the other large. Here. the first country could not by itself meet the total demand of both countries for the good in which it specializes. Thus. the large country would have to produce both commodities to satisfy its demand. being incompletely specialized. while the small country is completely specialized. The assumption of constant unit cost can also be relaxed. Increasing costs (diminishing marginal returns) and decreasing costs (increasing marginal returns) can be 21 examined in a comparative cost framework without negating the general results of the model. To relax the assumption of constant costs. other factors of production must be introduced. The assumptions of the labor theory of value can easily be replaced with the opportunity costs: assuming the availability of all its resources. a country can shift some of them from one line of production to another. 8 Then the price ratio (or rate of exchange) between commodities can be obtained from their opportunity costs. The opportunity cost of steel is the amount of texti le that must be given up to get an additional amount of steel regardless of whether it were labor. capital. or some other factor that were shifted from textile to steel production. Its Opportunity cost is the amount of steel that must be sacrificed for an additional quantity of textile. In a constant cost model. there is a constant rate of substitution in production between any two commodities. In a multifactor model with diminishing marginal returns. the substitution in production of the two commodities becomes limited so that the possibility of incomplete specialization emerges as the general result of the model. In addition. the division of labor will be carried out less than under constant costs. since the comparative disadvantage at the margin diminishes and finally disappears. Graham takes this one step farther and states that 22 because trade leads to the development of special ization. the combined output may be smaller than if there were no trade at all. This condition would occur when a country's exports are produced under diminishing returns. while non- traded and import competing goods are produced under increasing returns. This is provided that the increase in total money values of production in one country is less than the decrease in the other country. i H k h r I Jones (1979) argues that the sharp distinction often drawn between the Ricardian comparative cost and the Heckscher-Ohlin models can disappear when a multicommodity. multicountry framework such. as Graham's. is employed. The Ricardian and Heckscher—Ohlin models are distinguished from each other by the assumption concerning a commonly'shared technology. The Ricardian model assumes that the average productivity of labor is different between countries beeause they do not share the same common technological knowledge. If countries do not share the same technology. then factor prices will not equalize as in the Ricardian two by two model. The Heckscher-Ohlin model assumes that countries share a common technology. and thus factor prices do equalizeu However. as will be shown in the analysis. this is only a necessary and not a sufficient condition for factor price equalization. By employing a multicocunodity framework. it is demonstrated that factor prices need not equalize.and thus the sharp distinction of the two models fades. 23 The Ricardian and Heckscher-Ohlin models have two significant distinguihing features which are not dependent on the number of commodities and countries considered. The first is that the Ricardian model completely ignores differences in factor intensity. Homogeneous productive resources are converted into outputs at constant costs. so that in the Ricardian model it is necessary to concentrate on only one factor of production - labor.‘The Ricardian model also assumes that countries differ in the average productivity of labor in the same occupation without specifying the cause. whereas the Heckscher-Ohlin model is based on an assumption that knowledge of the best productive techniques is available»tolall countries. Jones concentrates on the role of factor endowments in determining production and trade patterns by considering two smal l countries which share access to the same technology but differ in their endowments of capital and labor. Unit- value isoquants are constructed for five commodities for these countries. Each unit-value isoquant shows all combinations of capital and labor that can produce 31 worth of output of that particular good. The country's capital- labor endowment ratio would dictate the location of production along this composite unit-value isoquant and the country’s wage/rent ratio. These unit-value isoquants are represented in Figure 2.1. 24 Figure 2.1. Unit-value Isoquant CAPITAL: L.) \_ I LABOR The fol lowing information about possible production patterns for this small country can be derived from Figure 2.1. (I) Some commodities will never be produced by this country because its technology in these commodities is inferior to that prevailing elsewhere in the world. This is illustrated by commodity 5. (2) Certain techniques for producing some comnodities wi l i never be observed regardless of the community's endowment base. This is illustrated by point G. If a ray from the origin representing the country's capital/labor endowment ratio cuts the locus between points 0 and E in Figure 2.1. then this country would specialize in commodity 3. It would then export commodity 3 in exchange for al 1 the other commodities. If the economy had a higher endowment proportion of capital. so that a ray from the origin to the endowment point cut the locus between E and F. the country would produce both commodities 3 and 4. and 25 import commodities 1.2. and S. In this way. the pattern of production depends on factor endowments. Figure 2.1 can be used to illustrate the wage/rent ratio that would correspond to any factor-proportions. The factor price ratio is shown by the slope of the inner locus ABCDEF at the point where it crosses the factor endowment ray. Figure 2.2 traces out the relationship between factor endowments and factor prices for a given set of world prices. Figure 2.2 Factor Endowments and Factor Prices WAGES/I RENTS w \ CAPITAL/LABOR At a low capital/labor ratio. the wage/rent ratio would also be low. and the country would specialize in commodity I. If the country"s capital/labor endowment ratio increases. it would now produce both commodities 2 and 1. For local variations of the capital/labor ratio near this production point the country remains incompletely specialized in 2 and 26 1. and factor prices are equalized at this level. corresponding to a two-by-two model. From this analysis. it can now be determined whether two small countries facing the same set of world prices and sharing the same technological knowledge will have their factor prices equalized. As illustrated in Figure 2.2. even when two countries share the same technology and are incompletely special ized in two commodities. their factor prices need not be equalized. This would occur when one country produces commodities 2 and 3. and the othercountry produces commodities 3 and 4. Although production functions may be identical. as assumed by the Heckscher-Ohl in model. the techniques actually adopted to produce commodity 3 will differ between countries because the wage/rent ratio is higher in the relatively capital-abundant country. The difference between countries in comparative labor productivities that is asserted by assumption in the Ricardian model can be deduced from differences in relative factor endowments in a Heckscher-Ohlin model. Thus. there is very little difference between the two models in a multicommodity framework. anclugion This chapter developed the theoretical foundationsof the classical comparative cost model beginning with the Ricardian model. The assumptions of the latter were relaxed with the introduction of money wages. a multicommodity framework. transportation costs. and incomplete 27 specialization to construct a more realistic model. With the relaxation of the assumptions. Jones demonstrated that the sharp distinction often drawn between the Ricardian and Heckscher-Ohl in models disappeared when a multicommodity. multicountry framework was employed. since factor prices need not equalize. The difference between countries in comparative labor productivities that is asserted by assumption in the Ricardian model can be deduced from differences in relative factor endowments in a Heckscher- Ohlin model. Viner (1937) pointed out that comparing the cost ratios of different commodities within the same country was valid if the ratios between costs are examined..All commodities produced by a country can be ranked internally in the order of their domestic costs of production. Each country would export the commodities in which its comparative advantage in terms of production costs is greatest and import those commodities which rank lowest (highest production costs). This provides the theoretical foundations for ranking industries in the subsequent chapters. The empirical tests of the comparative cost theory are reviewed in the next chapter. beginning with MacDougal l's analysis of the Ricardian hypothesis. Challenges to the Ricardianihypothesis and the subsequent relaxation of its assumptions are also examined. 28 F Qtnotgg 1The question of whether Ricardo can claim the credit for establishing the theory has been debated in the literature. The controversy stems from the fact that Colonel Torrens published an analysis of comparative advantage in 1808. The Economists Bgfute . and in 1815. An Essay m the Extgrml an Trage. while Ricardo's Pringiglgs appeared in 1817. However. Viner (1937) believes that despite Torrens' earlier publication. Ricardo is entitled to the credit for being the first to place an euphasis on the theory. the first to place the theory in an appropriate setting. and for obtaining a general acceptance of it by economists. In a similar vein. Chipman (1965) states that although Ricardo was influenced by Torrens's Extgrml Qgrn Mg. Ricardo added a great deal to the theory. He also states that both Torrens and Ricardo contributed in essential ways to the development of comparative advantage. but Torrens should be given credit for the principal discovery. 2The early comparative cost theories relied heavily on the labor theory of value. Haberler (1936) showed that the deductions obtained from using the labor theory of value do not depend on the validity of its assumptions. Thus it is possible to discard the labor theory. along with its unrealistic assumptions. without having to discard the results obtained from it. 3This section is based on Kreinin (1983). chapter 11. 4In contrast. Graham (1923) objected to the normal equilibrium position lying between the cost ratios and cal led this a "l imbo" ratio. Graham demonstrated conditions under which the terms of trade would 1 ie at one of the limits set by comparative advantage. This would occur when the two countries were of different economic sizes. and the economic importance of the two products were not the same in each country. Thus the demand of country A for country 8 products would not be the same as the reciprocal demand. Since these two demands will not be balanced. the terms of trade will be forced to one of the limits set by comparative costs. The appearance of a balance inside these limits would only be a slight coincidence. 5This section is based on Kreinin (1983). chapter 11. 6If we consider two countries. m and n. each producing goods 1.2."..i. then their respective unit labor costs can be represented as lim and lin. The degree of comparative advantage can be expressed as the ratio [(l Avail ))/(i lAvoil )] - [(I:mél1nfl'(£b9(lgag/Avoil’2)] - C. The industries in each coungry are examined relatIve to the manufacturing average. If C > I. then country m has a comparative advantage in the 29 production of good i. If C < 1. the country n has the advantage. Thus. the unit labor costs are first ranked internally and then international comparisons are made. See Deardorff (1980) and Kreinin (1982) for the justification of using the manufacturing average as the denominator. 7This section of the reformulated comparative costs theory is based on Kreinin (1983). chapter 11. BViner (1937. p. 490) is opposed to the linking of the labor theory to the classical theory of comparative advantage. ”Except for Ricardo. none of the classical expounders of the doctrine of the comparative costs. with the relatively uninportant and partial exception of James Mil l. was an exponent of a labor-cost theory of value." Viner also states that ”the association of the comparative- cost doctrine with the labor cost theory of value is a historical accident.” CHAPTER I I I REVIEW OF THE EHPIRICAL LITERATURE Classical trade theory states that international specialization is determined by comparative advantage based on relative productivity differentials among countries. It does not attempt to explain why the differences occur: rather. the assumption is that they exist and make trade be possible and beneficial. Relative differences in the wage structure and capital-labor ratios of some industries may distort the relative rankings determined by productivity differentials. Nevertheless. labor productivity captures the greatest portion of the variations. and hence the classical economists believed that additional factors were not sufficiently important to cause significant changes in the pattern of international trade as determined by relative labor productivity differences. The classical comparative cost theory was tested empirically several times. beginning with MacDougall. but these tests had limited success. A review of this empirical l iterature fol lows. MacDougal 1'; Original Formulgtign Using Rostas's productivity data for twenty-five British and U.S. industries. MacDougall (1951.1952) tested selected aspects of the classical comparative cost theory. 30 31 The empirical results were based on the Ricardian labor theory of value. Assuming a two-country world. Great Britain and the United States. each country will have a comparative advantage and export those goods for which its relative output per worker. (U.S./U.K.). exceeds its relative money wage rate in the respective industries. However. bilateral trade flows could not be uti l ized because the bulk of U.S. and U.K. exports in 1937 went to third markets. which became the basis for the tests. According to pre-World War II statistics from the Ministry of Labour and the Department of Labor. U.S. weekly wages in manufacturing industries were on average double those in Great Britain. Where U.S. output per worker was more than twice that of the British. the United States was expected to dominate the export market. and where the U.S. output per worker was less than twice that of the British. Britain was expected to dominate the export market. The empirical results indicated that 20 of the 25 industries (covering 97 percent of the sample by value) conformed to theoretical expectation. MacDougall found a strong inverse relationship between relative wage costs per unit of output (relative wages/output) and relative exports. and a positive relationship between relative output per worker and relative exports. When relative output per worker was plotted against relative exports on a double logarithmic scale. the regression line had a lepe of almost four and the resulting R2 was 0.64. This indicates that a one percent difference in 32 relative output per worker for a commodity was associated with 3-4 percent higher exports for the country with the greater productivity level. In the traditional Ricardian framework. with perfect markets and homogeneous products. the exports of each country should go to the other. Where either country had a comparative advantage. however small. the country would capture the whole export market. Instead. the majority of U.S. and U.K. exports in 1937 went to third markets. with little trade between themselves. In industries where Britain had the comparative advantage in 1937. U.K. exports to the United States were only a fraction of one percent of total LLS. consumption in that commodity. Similarlyu in industries where the United States had the comparative advantage in 19373 LLS. exports to Britain were more substantial. but still only a small percentage of total British consumption in that commodity. One explanation is that the assumptions of the Ricardian model do not hold in the real world. Instead. with imperfect markets. each country obtained the larger share of the third market where it had the comparative advantage. and each countrytended to capture a larger share of the third market the greater its comparative advantage. As theory would suggest. this was the expected result when the assumptions are relaxed. confirming the labor theory of comparative costs. The existence of high tariffs is a second explanation for the lack of penetration of the U.S. and U.K. domestic 33 markets. In 1937. U.S. tariffs fully offset Britain's comparativeladvantage in almost every commodity with the exceptions of cement and coke. where transportation costs are high. and footwear. where the British advantage was smal l. U.S. tariffs were much higher on commodities where Britain had a comparative advantage than on other commodities. British tariffs fully offset U.S. comparative advantage in paper and glass. while they only partly offset tLS. comparative advantage in machinery. motor cars. wireless sets and values. pig iron. and tin cans. But by 1950. MacDougall (1962) found a general reduction in U.S. tariffs. In particular. this was most noticeable for the commodities in which the United States had a comparative disadvantage. In contrast to the 1937 LLS. tariff rates. the 1950 rates seldom offset Britain's comparative advantage. Tests of the r tiv C st Th r Balassa (1963) and Stern (1962) continued and updated MacDougall's original work. They examined the relative importance of productivity. wages. and capital costs in determining the pattern of exports for selected manufacturing industries in the United States and Great Britain. In addition. Stern examined the relative wage structure and export performance of the two countries in 1959 to determine whether changes in comparative advantage had occurred. Paige and Bombach”s I950 productivity estimates for 44 manufacturing industries in the United States and the United 34 Kingdom were utilized by Stern. Balassa's sample covered only 28 industries. representing 43.1 percent of the manufacturing output in Britain and 41.4 percent in the United States. The productivity'data were measured as net output per worker: gross output minus purchased inputs other than labor. divided by total employees. The relative wage and output per worker measures are man-year figures. while the employment figures include direct and indirect labor. Net cost ratios were included as an explanatory variable to measure capital costs and profit per unit of output in addition to the unit labor costs. Thus. net cost ratios could provide some indication of relative resource productivity and could be important if the assumptions of the labor theory of value were relaxed. In 1950. the U.S. and U.K. mutual trade was still a smal l percentage of the total trade of each. Since most of the U.S. and U.K. trade was with third countries. Stern treated the rest of the world as a third country. examining total U.S. and British exports in addition to their mutual trade. Balassa. in contrast. excluded mutual trade between the United States and Britain since the differential tariff rates would distort trade patterns. Instead. the effect of 1950 relative productivity differentials on relative export performance for 1951 in third countries was examined. Still. corrections for the discriminatory effects of commonwealth preferences and other distorting factors were not accounted 35 for. In examining the impact of productivity differences on export performance. the elasticity of substitution between U.S. and British exports of the same commodity was assumed to exceed unity. Thus. a positive relationship was expected between relative productivity differentials and export performance with the resulting regressions in logarithmic form as fol lows: .Belesse log EI/EII . -1.76 + 1.59 log 91/911 R2 . 0.74; (3.1) (0.18) Stern log 51/511 = -0.68 + 1.27 log PI/PII R2 - 0.19. (3.2) (0.43) where E is the export performance. P is productivity. I is country one. and 11 is country two. To provide consistent reporting. all regression results providing R have been converted to R2. The coefficients in both equations were significant and have the correct signs. The difference in the magnitude of the coefficients and R2 between the two equations is due to Balassa's smal ler sample size. By excluding industries which may be dominated by demand factors or are nontraded. he was able to obtain a higher R2. In addition. Stern found that relative wage differentials between the two countries had narrowed between 1950 and 1959. When comparing the two periods. each country experienced export gains in the industries in which it had a comparative disadvantage. This 36 wasattributed to relative productivity increases in the comparative disadvantage industries for each country. In an attempt to improve the regression results. wage ratios were added as a determinant of export performance. The resulting regression results are: fiauesse log EI/EII = -5.16 + 1.46 logPI/PII + 1.25 logWI/WII. (3.3) (0.33) (0.57) R2 . 0.77 Stern incorporates wage ratios into unit labor costs by dividing the output per worker ratios into the wage ratios. The results are as follows: Stern log 51/511 = 0.01 -1.40 log y R2 s 0.18: (3.4) (0.59) where y is unit labor costs. These results are similar to the ones obtained in equations 3.1 and 3.2: however. although the wage variable in equation 3.3 was significant at the 95 percent level. it had the wrong sign. Despite the statistical significance of log WI/WII. Balassa states that no definite relationship between wage rates and relativerexport performance can be established since the R2 did not differ significantly between equations 3.1 and 3.3. 1 His reason is that productivity differences were not offset by higher wages in high productivity industries: instead. productivity differences were the primary factors in determining export performance. One reason wage ratios might not be an important factor in explaining relative export performance 37 is that causation runs in both directions between the variables. While lower wages could lead to improved export performance. the latter may also cause wages to increase in an industry. Another reason wage ratios and export performance might not be correlated is that wage rankings of industries are similar among countries. A similar proposition. first advanced by'Taussig. states that wage rankinglare similar among countries because there is little competition between the labor forces of various industries. Interindustry wage differentials are determined by the disutility and regularity'of'work. the required skill levels.land other factors which are uniform in all countries: thus. wage differentials should be smaller than productivity differentials. In empirical tests of this proposition. Caves (1960). Kravis (1956b). Lary (1968). Lebergott (1947). and Balassa (1963) have shown that the rankings of industries by hourly earnings of workers are similar. Kravis compared the ranking of average hourly earnings in 20 manufacturing industries for Japan and the United States obtaining a coefficient of rank correlation of 0.82: he concluded that ”for most industries. international differences in productivity are greater than international differences in wages" (1956b. p. 68). Lary analyzed average annual wages in 13 industry groups for 11 countries. The ranking of industries from low to high wages was found to be similar in the seven developed countries (the United States. Canada. Sweden. Australia. the 38 United Kingdom. Germany. and France). but among the four developing countries (Mexico. Japan. Brazil. and India) the ranking was less consistent. Stanley Lebergott found that in the post-World War 11 years. interindustry wage differentials were almost identical among the United States. the United Kingdom. and Canada. while differing slightly for Sweden. This was brought out by Balassa. who obtained a coefficient of variance of 37.1 for productivity ratios and 10.7 for wage ratios. The last relationship explored is between relative export performance and net cost ratios. where net costs refer to per unit cost and profits in addition to labor costs. The results are as fol lows: Balassa 169 51/511 = 6.16 - 1.59 log NI/NII R2 = .50: (3.5) (0.30) £159.10 log 51/511 . 0.01 -1.41 log NI/NII R2 - 0.13: (3.6) (0.59) where NI/NII - relative unit costs. The results are also similar to equations 3.1 and 3.2 but with a higher standard error and lower coefficient of determination. These results confirm the classical theory. indicating that the relative export performance of the United States and the United Kingdom fol lowed establ ished lines of comparative advantage as suggested by labor productivity. The introduction of additional variables seemed to modify the results slightly. while differences in capital costs per 39 unit of output did not seem to have any significant effect on export performance. Additional Tests for Other Pairs of Countries Kreinin (1969) provides a critical analysis of the comparative cost theory as formulated by MacDougall. He expands the analysis by examining cross-sectional data for three pairs of countries other than the United States and the United Kingdom. Canada and Australia. Canada and the United Kingdom. and the United States and Canada were examined for the years 1948 and 1950-1951. Time series data were also examined for the United States and the United Kingdom over the period 1958-1965. Intracountry trade was negligible in the cross- sectional analysis for Canada and Australia because they serve different markets due to the distance involved and other traditional factors: thus. exports to third markets had to be considered. At the official exchange rate prevailing in 1950. average earnings per employee in Canadian manufacturing industries were double those in Australia. According to the Ricardian hypothesis. Canadian export volume should exceed Australia's in industries where the productivity index islebove 200 percent. andlCanadian export volume should fall below Austral ia's where the ratio is less than 200 percent. However. more than half of the 20 industries examined performed contrary to theory. Relative wage costs were derived by dividing the productivity ratio into the wage rate ratio. Relative 4D exports were then correlated with relative wage costs. with the expectation of a negative coefficient. However. this relationship was insignificant. Kreinin attributed this to the lack of variation in the interindustry wage structure in the two countries and in the ranking by comparative advantage. An additional factor is that the dependent variable. relative export. is limited by the fact that Canada and Australia have few common markets. Thus. extension of MacDougall’s analysis to this pair of countries is questionable. In the analysis for Canada and the United Kingdom. relative exports were not found to be correlated with either relative costs or price variables. However. the regression was severely limited by its small sample size. and no conclusive results are possible. The UAL and Canadian results indicated that a large share of their industries. total trade was intracountry. Thus. a study of this pair of countries provides a close approximation of the simple Ricardian two-country model. Unlike that model. incomplete specialization due to increasing costs. product differentiation. and trade barriers prevented post-trade commodity prices from being equalized internationally. These factors also caused trade in each commodity group to flow in both directions. Taking this into consideration. intracountry exports were found to be correlated with labor productivity and labor costs. The results expressed in logarithmic form are as follows: 41 x. = 0.37 + 5.50 yl R2 = 0.43; (3.8) (1.76) x. = 1.37 - 6.68 y2 R2 = 0.38: (3.9) (2.24) where x. is intracountry exports. VI is the labor productivity ratio.land Y2 the labor cost ratio. These results adhere more closely to the Ricardian hypothesis than do the previous results. Nevertheless. this sample deleted one fourth of the industry groups: when all 21 industries were included. the R2 dropped to»0.2.1flwile the parameters became statistically'insignificant. Time series data was also examined for the United States and the United Kingdom in 25 industries for the period 1958-1965. Changes over time in relative labor productivity were correlated with changes in relative export performance to third markets. with the expectation of a positive coefficient. Only six industries exhibited significant positive relationships. while eight exhibited negative relationships. and eleven exhibited none. Three of the six which showed strong positive relationships - leather. pulp. and glass - are characterized by homogeneous commodities. The problem is that with only eight annual observations there are not enough degrees of freedom on which to base any definitive conclusions. The MacDougal l—Stern analysis was then integrated by examining the common commodities in both studies. Changes over time for relative labor productivity were then correlated to changes in relative export performance for the United States and the United Kingdom over the years 1937. 42 1950. and 1959. The results indicate that one-third of the sample did not COHFOWflitO expected behavior. Because this analysis is based on one or two degrees of freedom. no definitive conclusions can be reached. Finally. time series data was examined for automobiles in six EurOpean countries for the years 1955. 1960. and 1965. When changes in relative labor productivity were correlated with relative export performance for sets of these European countries. Kreinin found little or no support fer the Ricardian hypothesis. Kreinin concluded that his evidence did not support the simple Ricardian hypothesis. Rather. factors other than supply. such as product differentiation and demand. determine the pattern of trade. For the case of differentiated commodities. labor productivity may only set the limits to the terms of trade. whereas demand conditions determine the exact terms of trade. The major constraint to using labor productivities for differentiated commodities is that the limits to trade may be wide. Evaluation‘gf the MacDougall Ageroach Bhagwati (1969) and Stern (1975) were critical of the MacDougall-Balassa-Stern (M-B-S) approach because these early empirical tests (including Stern’s) were too simplistic. Since M-B-S assumed labor was the only significant factor of production. measures of comparative labor productivity were employed as a proxy for comparative costs. Bhagwati and Stern cal l for a general framework for 43 determining trade patterns and are skeptical of the simple Ricardian approach. finding it difficult to adapt the one- factor Ricardian model to a multifactored world. Stern and Bhagwati state that treating labor productivity as an exogenous variable and as the most important determinant of comparative cost differences is limiting: therefore. concentration on labor productivity instead of other factor productivities is purely arbitrary. If human capital and other capital inputs into natural resources are considered. comparative capital productivity could be significant. and a multifactor model should be adopted. Thus. tests of the Ricardian hypothesis should be based on intercountry differences in total factor productivity. not just labor. Nevertheless. because of the increasing importance)of'multinationals in international trade. capital inputs have become mobile among countries and its price equalized. If there is little variation in capital prices. differential labor costs remain the important factor. Bhagwati and Stern state that since the Ricardian model emphasizes comparative differences in production functions. tests of the Ricardian model should be developed in terms of comparisons of production functions. The expected results are that a country"s exports would be concentrated in its relatively most efficient industries and its imports in its least efficient ones. Along these lines. Minhas (1962) has compared the isoquants of several countries and found that 44 except for a pure scale factor. all the isoquants had essentially'the same parameters. Bhagwati and Stern conclude that Minhas has devised a method for testing the Ricardian hypothesis in a more general manner. Stryker (1968) attempts to incorporate this approach in testing the comparative cost model. The problemiwith this method lies in the choice of the production function to estimate. Since different production functions exhibit different properties. the choice of any particular type wil l influence the results. Thus. this more genenal approach needs further theoretical development. Bhagwati states that a sufficient assumption for the Ricardian hypothesis to hold is for the labor productivity ratios to be a monotonically increasing function of the price ratios. In testing this assumption. Bhagwati found that the linear regression between labor productivity'and price ratios fit poorly. In addition. the linear relationship between comparative unit labor costs and export price ratios had a poor fit. From these results. Bhagwati concluded that both relationships are insignificant. 2 When relative inter-country wage rates were included as a separate and additional explanatory variable. a slight improvement over the simple correlation between export price ratios and labor productivities alone was found. Bhagwati (1969. pp. 22-23) states that his results "cast sufficient doubt on the usefulness of the Ricardian approach” and that there is no evidence to support the Ricardian hypothesis since "labor productivity'.“. is not a 45 datum in the sense that production functions are)‘ Even if an empirical relationship is established between relative exports and variations in relative labor productivity. the fundamental question of what determines comparative cost differences cannot be answered. The reason is that the Ricardian model simply assumes the existence of comparative cost differences. Thus. Bhagwati and Stern conclude that the Ricardian model is of limited importance in explaining the composition of international trade. Extension of the MacDougallgApprgggh J.D. Stryker (1968) extends the M—B-S analysis by incorporating capital inputs. labor inputs. differences in technology. economies of scale. and relative factor prices into a comparative cost model. thus meeting some of the criticism of Bhagwati and Stern. Time series and cross- sectional data are examined for the United States and Canada for the period 1949—1962. The first part of Stryker's study develops a two- country. partial equilibrium model which examines some of the factors underlying international price competition. The model is: 0 = ALGKB + R: (3.10) where O is the quantity of output produced: L is the labor input: K is the capital input: R is the raw material input: A is a proportionality parameter: a and 8 are the elasticity coefficients of value added with respect to labor and capital (V = O - R. where V is value added). Value added 46 is in constant dollars: labor input is in man-hours of production and nonproduction workersl the capital VBFIBDIB was estimated as the deflated book value of the gross capital stock. The assumptions of the model are as follows: 1. The manufacturing production function is subject to constant returns. 2. Labor and capital are homogeneous. 3. Raw materials are obtained from outside the manufacturing sector and are initially supplied by domestic sources. 4. The production of raw materials is subject to diminishing returns. 5. Perfect competition exists in all markets. 6. All firms are in long run equilibrium so that a single set of factor prices faces each within a country. 7. The parameters of the production functions differ between countries. 8. All firms engage in average cost pricing. The supply of manufacturing commodities is a positive function of the ratio of foreign to domestic prices for the commodity. and although scale effects in manufacturing can change the slope of commodity supply curves. the analysis is fundamentally’the same. The model expressing the relationship between relative export growth in the United States and Canada and the relative growth of labor productivity for a cross-sectional 47 analysis of 24 industries is as fol lows: [oi/X)”. - (me... = a + b[((.v/L)/(V/L))us - (3.11) ((Q/L)/(V/L))ca1.. Value added and labor data were collected on an establishmentbasis. while capital stock data were collected from firms. Since the two are not always classified in the same industry. problems in data compatibility may occur. In some cases where large firms own plants in several industries. part of the value of capital stock reported for a particular industry exists in establishments classified in another industry. Since tariffs can affect the exports of two countries differently at a given time. exports in three separate markets are examined. The first dependent variable is the difference between the relative rates of change of exports to third markets: the second is the difference between the relative rates of growth of reciprocal exports. The latter examines the effects of average cost changes on both exports and imports. since exports from the United States to Canada are the same as imports of Canada from the United States and vice versa. The third dependent variable is the difference between relative rates of growth of total exports. While tariffs affect the exports of two countries differently at a given time. changes in relative cost advantages will not be affected as long as the tariff rates are not changed during the period considered. Changes in external demand do not affect this analysis since a change in world demand is reflected in a change in international 48 prices. and this affects all countries equally; However. international prices are not the sole factor for international competition. and thus product differentiation may be an important factor for international competition which may modify the results. The results of equation 3.11 are as fol lows: Dependent variable a b R2 Third-market exports -0.022 1.975 0.153 (0.871) Reciprocal exports -0.019 1.715 0.128 (0.823) Total exports -0.024 1.927 0.207 (0.728) The results indicate that the coefficients and the coefficients of determination are significantly different from zero at the 0.05 level. although the Rz’s are low. Thus these results indicate that labor productivity'is an important factor in determining the pattern of trade. An attempt is then made to determine whether increases in the amount of capital employed in production may have offset changes in labor productivity. The findings show that the relationship between changes in exports and changes in labor productivity have not been offset by changes in the capital stock. This is due to capital being mobile between the United States and Canada. thus equalizing its cost. The role of technological innovation is also examined in an attempt to determine the underlying cause of differences in productivity of the two countries. The 49 findings are that the increases in productivity and the growth of exports over time are related to the differing rates of technological progress taking place within manufacturing industries. Stryker's evidence suggests that changes in the structure of'LLS. and Canadian exports were related to changes in average labor costs for the period examined. Within this framework. labor productivity is a useful proxy for total factor productivity. however. the differences in labor productivity are not explained by the comparative cost model. Stryker attributes these differences in productivity to differences in technological innovation. Jggtificgtion of Labor Costs In examining labor’s importance as a factor of production and a major component of total cost. labor's share of national income must be determined. Dennison (1967) found that labor income was almost 80 percent of net national income for the United States. Canada. and northwestern EurOpe. Labor shares this high can only occur if high proportions for labor income characterize a majority of the individual industries. If labor costs are a large part of value added. differences in either relative wage rates or relative labor productivities will play an important role in the structure of trade. In an analysis of the steel and motor vehicle industries. Kreinin (1984. pp. 41-42) concentrates on the labor cost of production because of ”its overwhelming 50 contribution to total production costs.” Labor costs were estimated to constitute 46 percent of total production costs for the motor vehicle industry. In addition. that industry is composed of multinationals which transfer capital in the production of components” partsw and final assembly’among many nations so as to minimize costs. In this way. labor costs determine plant location» Thus. an emphasis on wage and labor productivity differences for countries by industry appears to be justified. The question of whether the differences in output per worker are reflected in export prices and international trade is an important one. Rostas’s 1937 data on productivity levels in the United States and the United Kingdom are a measure of the gross output of an industry in real terms. In contrast. Paige and Bombach’s 1950 data are a measure of the net value added in an industry in real terms. The export price ratios used in all the studies were unit values of individual commodities. which are conceptually! closer to measures of gross output rather than to net value added. Studies employing the 1937 data displayed a close correlation between export price ratios and labor productivity while studies employing 1950 data showed little or no correlation. From the way the data are constructed. a close correlation between prices and net value added could occur only'if the commodity and industry definitions were the same and the relationships between output and material purchases fromlother industries were the same between the two countries. Thus previous attempts to establish a SI correlation between export price ratios and labor productivity ratios failed due to the lack of conceptual and statistical compatibility in the data. and they do not provide evidence against the Ricardian hypothesis. ngegggtive Cost Theory Refgrmulated Anderson and Kreinin (1981) and Kreinin (1982.1984.I985) analyzed the motor vehicle and steel industries by examining the cost advantage of an industry relative to all other manufacturing industries within the same country instead of between countries. This approachlallows industries to be ranked internally by the inverse of their production costs equivalent to a ranking by comparative advantage. Unit labor costs. consistinglof labor compensation and productivity. were employed as an approximation of total production costs. If an industry experiences a rise in labor compensation. or a fall in productivity relative to the national manufacturing average. it will fall in ranking by comparative advantage. Anderson and Kreinin confined their study to the United States over the period 1957-1977. while Kreinin in the three later articles examined the United States. Japan. and the industrialized European countries (German automobiles. and steel and iron only for the rest) over the period 1964-1980. The results indicated that between 1957 and 1977. labor compensation in the~LLS. iron and steel industries increased faster than in all manufactures. but labor productivity increased at a rate below the manufacturing average. causing 52 a fall in the ranking. Over .the period 1964-1980. unit labor costs in U.S. iron and steel grew faster than the manufacturing average. with the difference between the two widening. Thus. U.S. steel fell in ranking by comparative advantage because of relatively high labor compensation and relatively low labor productivity. In contrast. Japan's iron and steel industry was able to keep its unit labor costs in line with the manufacturing average and maintain its ranking by unit labor costs. German iron and steel also improved its internal ranking with increases in labor productivity and decreases in compensation relative to the manufacturing average. French and British iron and steel lost ground by comparative advantage in a manner similar to the United States. U.S. motor vehicles improved their ranking between 1957 and 1967. While labor productivity increased rapidly after 1967. compensation increased even faster. causing the motor vehicle industry to fall in ranking after 1967. Other factors relating to managerial decisions. such as product mix (large verses small cars). also played a role in the motor vehicle industry's deterioration. The Japanese motor vehicle industry was able to keep unit labor costs in line with the Japanese manufacturing average and maintain-its ranking. German motor vehicles were able to increase labor productivity at the same rate as all manufactures between 1962 and 1966. After 1967. labor productivity increased at a rate below that of al 1 German 53 manufacturing. with a pronounced moderation after 1974. Labor compensation kept pace with the manufacturing average. causing unit labor costs to increase after 1975. Therefore. Kreinin states that the German motor vehicle industry appears to be losing its comparative advantage. m The work of MacDougall. Balassa. Stern. and Stryker confirms the comparative cost theory. Using 1937 data. MacDougall feund a strong inverse relationship between relative U.S. and U.K. wage costs per unit of output and relative exports. and a positive relationship between relative output per worker and relative exports. Balassa and Stern's results indicated that the 1950 relative U.S. and U.K. export performance followed established lines of comparative advantage as suggested by labor productivity. The introduction of differences in capital costs per unit of output did not have any significant effect on export performance. Stryker's time series evidence suggested that changes in Udi.and Canadian exports were correlated with changes in labor productivity. and that the latter is a useful proxy for total factor productivity. although its differences are not explained by the comparative cost model. Stryker attributed these differences to technological innovation. In contrast. Kreinin concluded that his evidence did not support the simple Ricardian hypothesis. and that factors other than supply. such as product differentiation 54 and demand. determined the pattern of trade. For differentiated commodities. labor productivity sets the limits to the terms of trade. which may be wide. whereas demand conditions determine the exact terms of trade. Bhagwati and Stern were also critical of the M-B-S approach because it was too simplistic. and they call for a multifactor framework in determining trade patterns. In tests of the Ricardian hypothesis. Bhagwati found a poor fit between 1950 relative labor productivity and price ratios and the relationship between comparative unit labor costs and export price ratios. When relative intercountry wage rates were included as an explanatory variable. a slight improvement was found. The question of whether the differences in output per worker are reflected in export prices was addressed by Daly. Since earlier studies measured export prices and labor productivity on a different basis. their failure to establish a correlation between export price ratios and labor productivity ratios was due to the lack of conceptual and statistical compatibility in the data: they did not provide evidence against the Ricardian hypothesis. By reformulating the comparative cost theory to examine internal changes in unit labor costs. Kreinin has developed an effective tool which yields information useful in making policy decisions. Industries concerned with import competition can decrease their unit labor costs by decreasing labor compensation. increasing productivity. or both. to improve their ranking by comparative advantage and 55 trade performance. The next chapters incorporate the Kreinin approach in the analysis of manufacturing industries in the United States. Japan. Germany. the United Kingdom. and Italy. The performance of each industryms unit labor cost and its components are examined in relation to the manufacturing average to determine the effect on its internal ranking. 56 Footnotes 1Simply because the wage vafiable has the wrong sign and does not "add much” to the R . is not a valid reason to declare it insignificant. See Schmidt (1976) and Johnson(1972). 2Goodness of fit is not the correct criterion for judging whether a relationship is significant. See Schmidt(1976) and Johnson (1972). CHAPTER IV DISAGREGATED CROSS-SECTIONAL EVIDENCE FOR UNIT LABOR COSTS IN THE UNITED STATES This chapter investigates the effect of unit labor costs on the trade flows of U.S. manufacturing industries for 1967 and 1980. The first part develops an internal ranking of 139 industries for these years and formulates a cross-sectional model for determining the effect of unit labor costs on international trade. The second part arranges the industries into low. medium. and high technology categories and analyzes the performance of their unit labor costs. The unit costs of production is the inverse of comparative advantage and is the criterion for the internal rankings. The lower the unit costs of production. the higher is an industry"s ranking by comparative advantage. Unit costs of production can be approximated by unit labor costs. which in turn are defined as the ratio of total labor compensation to labor productivity; Value added per employee is used as a proxy for labor productivity. Pol icy implications can be derived from the internal ranking of industries. If an industry’s level of labor costs is high relative to other industries. it would be ranked low by comparative advantage. For the industry to improve its 57 58 ranking. it must cut unit labor costs through a reduction in labor compensation or an increase in productivity. Data The industries are categorized by the Standard Industrtal Classification (SIC) system at the two-. three-. and four-digit leved. LLS. data for total compensation. value added. and total employees were obtained from various issues of two Bureau of the Census publications. Annual Survey gf Manufactures and the Censug 9f Mgnufgctures for 1967. 1972. and 1977. This chapter departs from past studies by using the total compensation of employees instead of merely wages. Total compensation is a more comprehensive measure of the cost structure among industries and is the better specified variable. Besides wages. it includes social security payments and employee fringe benefits. and among these are paid vacation time. health care. paid holidays. and personal absences. Total employees include production as well as clerical and administrative workers. LLS. data for export and import values by two-. three-. and four-digit SIC breakdown were collected from various issues of the Bureau of the Census. UL; Commodity Exgorts gag Imggrts a; Related 29 Outgut. Data for export and import values by eight-digit SIC breakdown were drawn from the LLS. Department of Commerce. U.S. Imgorts. Consumgtion _Qy Wgrld Areas. FT210. and DAL Exgorts Domestic Merchanise. FT610. The unit labor costs and net trade positions of U.S. 59 industries for 1967 and 1980 are displayed in Table 4.1. The complete tables. including the components of unit labor costs. are presented in the Appendix. TABLE 4.I U.S. 6D Industries. Unit Labor Costs and Net Trade Positions of 1967 and 1980 Industry 1980 1967 Unit a X-M b Unit a X-M b Labor Costs Labor Costs Meat Products 0.562 -766.1 0.612 -428.9 Dairy Products 0.370 -266.9 0.465 22.5 Preserved Fruits 0.379 N.A. 0.386 1.6 Grain Mill Products 0.265 2714.9 0.294 515.3 Bakery Products 0.488 -90.8 0.532 -13.1 Sugar. Confectionery 0.294 -2214.7 0.363 -624.4 Fats and Oils 0.303 3143.1 0.389 -48.5 Beverages 0.320 -1946.2 0.356 -477.8 Misc.Foods Kindred 0.297 237.4 0.321 381.6 Tobacco Products 0.220 991.6 0.216 129.6 Weaving Mills. Cotton 0.615 181.8 0.630 —28.2 Weaving Mills. Manmade 0.562 212.0 0.627 20.8 Weaving. Finished. Wool 0.554 ~81.9 0.553 -88.0 Narrow Fabric Mills 0.607 36.2 0.621 5.0 Knitting Mills 0.571 90.2 0.593 11.8 Textile Finishing 0.524 N.A. 0.645 N.A. Floor Covering Mills 0.463 7.2 0.420 -45.7 Yarn and Thread Mills 0.610 41.2 0.586 -39.3 Miscellaneous Textiles 0.535 -40.3 0.560 -273.2 Men’s and Boys’ Suits 0.626 -278.7 0.681 -20.7 Men’s and Boys' Furnishing 0.531 -1249.0 0.609 -92.7 Women's and Misses' Out. 0.562 -1013.9 0.600 -89.6 Women's. Children’s Under. 0.543 -84.2 0.561 1.5 Hats. Caps. and Millinery 0.560 -2264.6 0.676 -12.4 Children's Outerwear 0.554 -100.2 0.607 -226.5 Fur Goods 0.491 -10.4 0.545 1.8 Misc. Apparel and Accs. 0.575 -497.8 0.612 -28.1 Misc. Fabricated Textile 0.574 176.7 0.594 35.7 Sawmills and Planing Mill 0.621 ~1026.5 0.535 173 Millwork. Plywood. Struc. 0.643 -335.2 0.637 -272.2 Wood Containers 0.602 13.1 0.658 -169.6 Wood Buildings.Mobile Home 0.594 107.6 0.622 1.0 Misc. Wood Products 0.557 -445.8 0.587 -63.6 Household Furniture 0.583 N.A. 0.603 N.A. Office Furniture 0.506 N.A. 0.528 N.A. Public Bldg..Related Furn. 0.585 N.A. 0.631 N.A. Partitions and Fixtures 0.598 N.A. 0.607 N.A. Misc. Furniture and Fixt. 0.541 N.A. 0.605 N.A. Pulp Mills Paper Mills.Building Paper Paperboard Mills Converted Paper Paperboard Cont. Boxes Misc. Building Paper.Board Mills Newspapers Periodicals Books Misc. Publishing 61 Table 4.1 continued Commercial Printing Manifold Business Forms Greeting Card Publishing Blankbooks and Bookbinding Printing Trade Services Industrial Plastic Materials. Drugs Soaps. Paints. Cleaners. Inorganic Chem. Syn. Toilet Allied Products Industrial Organic Chem. Agricultural Chem. Misc. Chemicals Petroleum Refining Paving and Roofing Mat. Misc. Petroleum.Coal Prod. Tires and Inner Tubes Rubber. Reclaimed Rubber Rubber 9 Plastic Plastic Footwear Hose Fabricated Rubber Misc. Leather Tanning Boot. Footwear. Plastics Shoe Cut Stock Leather Gloves Luggage Handbags and Purses Leather Goods Expt. Rubber 0.383 0.467 0.481 0.418 0.597 0.605 0.527 0.295 0.370 0.420 0.617 0.427 0.362 0.545 0.624 0.352 0.403 0.306 0.201 0.366 0.290 0.220 0.348 0.158 0.433 0.319 0.558 0.679 0.459 0.872 0.634 0.514 0.549 0.547 0.512 0.731 0.503 0.589 0.509 0.2 -2595.8 1293.9 480.1 134.1 -51.8 -26.5 161.7 198.4 N.A. 92.1 4.3 4.2 N.A. 7.3 454.9 4219.5 674.9 536.5 213.4 4260.3 2365.9 513.6 -11538.0 12.4 348.3 -746.3 -489.7 -0.2 117.5 N.A. N.A. 43.3 -72.7 -2348.3 -46.9 -222.2 -444.6 -43.9 0.418 0.534 0.396 0.465 0.606 0.506 0.582 0.372 0.385 0.515 0.647 0.476 0.454 0.640 0.722 0.306 0.389 0.260 0.195 0.416 0.374 0.311 0.441 0.234 0.458 0.323 0.496 0.667 0.611 0.607 N.A. 0.538 0.652 0.596 0.605 0.680 0.568 0.643 0.631 -805.4 208.4 86.9 21.9 N.A. -0.6 72.6 73.5 -I4.7 52.4 N.A. -0.2 -2.1 N.A. 739.1 625.2 232.3 105.8 50.9 38.7 111.4 209.3 -550 11.9 2.0 -II.8 -81.5 2.4 N.A. N.A. N.A. -2601 -O.4 -171.5 -27.3 -10.9 -62.1 -0.9 62 Table 4.1 continued Flat Glass Glass Products of Glass Cement. Hydraulic Structural Clay Pottery Concrete. Cut Stone Misc. Nonmetallic Miner. Gypsum. Plaster Blast Furnace. Steel Iron. Steel Foundries Primary Nonferrous Metals Secondary Nonferrous Nonferrous Rolling Nonferrous Foundries Misc. Primary Metal Metal Cans Cutlery. Handtools Plumbing. Heating Fabricated Struc. Screw Machine. Bolts Metal Forgings. Stamp Metal Services Ordnance Misc. Fab. Metal Engines. Turbines Farm. Garden Machinery Construction Mach. Metalworking Mach. Special Industry Mach. General Industry Mach. Office. Computing Mach. Refrigeration Misc. Machinery Electric Distributing Elect. Industrial Household Appliances Elec. Lighting. Wiring Radio. TV Receiving Communication Equip. Electronic Components Misc. Elec. Equip. -5380.6 115.1 -941.1 -2672.5 1306.4 N.A. 4.3 N.A. 35.4 3.7 N.A. -375.3 N.A. N.A. N.A. -45.2 2025.2 344.7 N.A. N.A. 379.4 2676.1 N.A. 1730.9 N.A. 264.8 1019.5 N.A. 198.2 -3022.4 87.3 696.0 912.1 0.539 0.511 0.515 0.353 0.626 0.661 0.490 0.667 0.528 0.580 0.718 0.337 0.510 0.494 0.640 0.613 0.483 0.508 0.549 0.609 0.582 0.637 0.608 0.605 0.564 0.583 0.534 0.560 0.621 0.606 0.585 0.485 0.500 0.625 0.547 0.570 0.489 0.482 0.514 0.699 0.623 0.545 -29.9 56.3 0.3 -10.2 5.5 -79.2 3.5 -13.3 52.8 -864.3 48.0 N.A. 10.3 N.A. 23.1 N.A. 50.1 50.7 209.9 -15.3 201.0 N.A. -31.2 111.3 376.3 146.1 N.A. 226.3 N.A. 415.4 N.A. 362.2 N.A. 150.8 207.0 59.3 N.A. -397.6 299.1 225.9 22.1 63 Table 4.1 continued Motor Vehicles 0.708 -13882.7 0.512 -65.8 Aircraft. Parts 0.598 N.A. 0.715 1737.3 Ship. Boat Building 0.760 526.0 0.806 56.8 Railroad Equipment 0.545 51.0 0.623 131.3 Motorcycles. Bicycles 0.543 -1516.8 0.573 —99.5 Guided Missiles. Space 0.637 N.A. N.A. N.A. Transportation Equip. 0.605 404.7 0.605 -16.8 Engineering. Scien. Inst. 0.508 N.A. 0.583 132.8 Measuring. Controlling 0.576 N.A. 0.579 277.1 Optical Instruments 0.501 202.7 0.631 -29.2 Medical Instruments 0.483 682.0 0.489 113.3 Ophthalmic Goods 0.543 -174.3 0.554 -11.2 Photographic Equip. 0.314 612.3 0.375 192.9 Watches. Clocks 0.527 -941.5 0.595 -125.6 Jewelry. Silver 0.476 -1329.6 0.545 -122.2 Musical Instruments 0.614 36.6 0.667 ~28.1 Toys. Sporting Goods 0.418 -1311.4 0.513 -117.3 Pens. Office. Art Goods 0.444 122.5 0.533 27.4 Costume Jewelry 0.542 -378.1 0.526 -83.3 Misc. Manufactures 0.558 83.3 0.568 N.A. All Manufactures 0.543 0.471 (a) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value added. (b) Units for net trade are millions of dollars. 64 The Models This section examines the effect of unit labor costs on the trade performance of manufacturing industries in a cross sectional model for 1967 and 1980. A double log form of the equation is used to obtain elasticities and because the Ricardian hypothesis traditionally'has been tested that way; The equations are as follows: X/M‘ , A1 + 42 L, + 01. log(X/M)i = 81 + 82 log(L). + U2. Where X/M = trade performance: L = unit labor costs (total compensation/value added); U1.U2 = error terms: and i = industries (1.....139). The coefficients are A1.BI = intercept terms: A2.B2 sensitivity of trade performance to (4.1) (4.2) changes in unit labor costs. The expected sign of 82 is negative. 65 Table 4.2 OLS Results from the Cross-Sectional Data 1980 Results: X/M I 6.70 - 8.34 L (4.11) (2.18) (4.17) R?- . 0.04 F-stat . 4.01 N s 112 0-11 stat = 2.21 109(X/M) a -1.22 - 1.60 109(L) (4.21) (0.36) (0.48) R2 = 0.09 F-stat . 11.10 N =112 o-w stat ..- 1.93 1967 Results: X/M a 16.54 - 21.20 L (4.12) (6.31) (11.58) R2 = 0.03 F-stat . 3.35 N = 115 D—W stat - 2.17 log(X/M) = - 0.90 - 1.51 Iog(L) (4.22) (0.45) (0.63) R2 . 0.05 F-stat - 5.68 N - 115 0-w stat . 1.82 The statistical results indicate that unit labor costs were>an important factor in explaining the trade flows of the U.S. during the two years examined.Although the R2 was low inlall regressions. the relationship between unit labor costs and trade performance was significant as indicated by the F-statistics. In addition. the coefficients of the explanatory variables were significant and of the correct sign. The low R2 are not a cause for concern since all the regression statistics were significant. Considering the multitude of factors affecting international trade flows. a low R2 was not unexpected since only one explanatory variable was used - unit labor costs. The goal of the 66 analysis was not to obtain high R2. but instead to generate significant coefficients of the correct sign. In addition to these results. an alternate specification. based on Deardorff"s model. is tested in Appendix C. Analysis of U.S. Manufacturing Industries This section analyzes the unit labor costs. which are presented in Table 4.1. of low. medium. and high technology manufacturing industries in the United States. The breakdown of industries into these three categories is based on Department of Commerce classifications. Each industryfls level of unit labor costs and its components. labor compensation and productivity. are examined in relation to the manufacturing average. If an industry’s unit labor costs increases relative to other manufacturing industries. its trade position is expected to suffer. Since this study concentrates on supply side considerations. all deviations in an industry's trade position cannot be explained. Nevertheless. supply factors can explain a large portion of the trade flows. ng Technology Inggstries The low technology industries have been grouped into four major categories: agricultural-based manufacturing. traditional low technology'products. forest products.(and nonmeta 1 products. As shown in Table 4.1. the United States held a strong comparative advantage in 1967 and 1980. as approximated by 67 unit labor costs. in the agricultural-based manufacturing industries. which consists of food products. beverages. and tobacco. They are generally characterized by high labor productivity and low compensation relative to all manufactures. The exception is the meat products industry. which displayed relatively low labor productivity levels and ranked 90 in 1980. From 1967 to 1980. all (LS. agricultural-based manufacturing industries were able to strengthen their position with decreases in unit labor costs. These reductions stemmed from increases in labor productivity and decreases in compensation relative to the manufacturing average. Despite lower unit labor costs. its trade position did not improve uniformly. Although grain mil l products. fats and oils. and tobacco products showed a significant improvement. the dairy products. sugar. and beverage industries experienced a marked deterioration. The United States helcia comparativeldisadvantage in the production of traditional low technology products. which encompass texti le. wearing apparel. leather products. and footwear. These industries have been grouped together because of similar cost structures and trade positions. Their cost structures are characterized by low levels of labor productivity and compensation relative to the manufacturing average and their trade flows are heavily regulated by multi- and bilateral trade agreements. 68 The United States was able to reduce its unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980 in the wearing apparel. leather products. and footwear by reducing labor compensation relative to all manufactures. In textiles. unit labor costs in the weaving mi ll and textile finishing industries were lowered. while those in wool weaving. yarn. thread. and floor covering mills increased. The wearinglapparel and footwear industries suffered trade deficits in 1967 and 1980. Except for children's outerwear products. the deficits increased between these two years even though unit labor costs decreased. Since supply considerations do not explain the trade patterns. trade restrictions and demand Factors must be the prime determinants of trade flows in these commodities. The forest products category consists of wood products. furniture. and paper products industries. All of these incur high transportation costs. which constricts trade flows and causes many of the products to be labeled nontraded goods. In 1967 and 1980. the United States held a comparative disadvantage in the manufacture of wood products and furniture. The exception was office furniture. which ranked 52 in 1980. The cause for the low rankings were the low levels of labor productivity relative to all manufactures. Since many of the wood and furniture products are non- traded. changes in their unit labor costs are expected to have little effect on trade flows. As shown in Tables 4.1 and 11-8 in the Appendix. the United States held a comparative advantage in the 69 manufacture of paper products. with the exceptions of paperboard (ranking 108) and building paper (ranking 114). The high rankings were caused by high labor productivity relative to all manufactures. Except for paperboard mills. the paper products industries were able to reduce unit labor costs between 1967 and 1980. In response. their trade position improved. The exception was paper mills. which despite lower unit labor costs experienced a large increase in its trade deficit. The nonmetal products classification consists of pottery and china. glass. and other nonmetal products. Generalizations regarding this classification are difficult because'of'the diversity'of the industries. The United States possessed a comparative disadvantage in the manufacture of pottery and china and glass products because of high unit labor costs. But whereas these were increased in the glass industry from 1967 to 1980. they were reduced in the the pottery and china industryu The latter recorded trade deficits in both years and despite reduction in unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980. its trade deficits mounted. Since its trade position was not responsive to supply considerations. demand factors are the major forces in determining trade flows. The other nonmetal products industries exhibited widely varying unit labor costs. Unit labor costs were low for cement. concrete. and nonmetallic minerals and high for structural clay and cut stones. Since nonmetal products are 70 subject to steep transportation costs. which cause them to be labeled nontraded goods. changes in unit labor costs in these industries would have little effect on their trade performance. Medium Technolggy Industries The medium technology industries are defined as iron and steel. nonferrous metals. metal products. energy. rubber. transport equipment (except for aircraft and guided missiles). and publishing. The United States held a comparative disadvantage in the manufacture of rubber in 1967 and 1980. The exception was reclaimed rubber production. where low unit labor costs prevailed. Labor productivity was above average in the tire and reclaimed rubber industries. below average among the rest of the industries. The rubber industry's ranking experienced a significant reduction from 1967 to 1980 because of a decrease in labor productivity and an increase in compensation relative to all manufactures. The escalation of its unit labor costs led to a rapid deterioration in the industry's trade deficit. In 1967. the United States held a comparative disadvantage in iron and steel foundries. and there were "moderate" unit labor costs in blast furnace steel production. By 1980. the latter was in a position of disadvantage because of escalations in labor compensation relative to all manufactures. These sharp increases aided in 71 turning a small trade deficit in 1967 into a large deficit in 1980. The United States held a comparative advantage in the primary and secondary nonferrous metals industries because of high labor productivity. and a comparative disadvantage irinonferrous foundries because'of low labor productivity’ relative to all manufactures. From 1967 to 1980. the primary nonferrous metals and rolling industries increased. while the secondary nonferrous metals decreased their unit labor costs. The response of trade flows to these changes was not consistent with the comparative costs theory. and thus demand is the important determinant of trade flows. In 1967. the transport equipment category displayed consistently high unit labor costs with the exception of motor vehicles. where these were low. However. by 1980 unit labor costs had increased significantly in this sector so that the entire category possessed high unit labor costs. The sharp increase was reflected in trade position of the motor vehicle industry. In 1967 it registered a small deficit. but by 1980. this had swelled to record proportions. The metal products industries have a heterogeneous cost structure. The manufacture of metal cans. plumbing materials. and heating equipment involves low'unit labor costs while the opposite is true of screw machines and metal forgings. Overall these industries reduced their unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980. but for those for which dataare 72 complete. their trade positions deteriorated. Thus. demand factors are the most important determinants of metal products’ trade flows. The United States held a comparative advantage in the publishing industries except for commercial printing (ranked 123) and printing trade services (ranked 124). Al 1 sectors reduced unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980. but since these industries generate low trade volumes. analysis of the category difficult. The United States appeared to exhibdt a comparative advantage in the energy industries that consists of petroleum refining and coal products. Because this category is overwhelmingly dominated by demand. which may distort the ranking. only a brief mention is made here. The high rankings for the energy industries stem from the extraordinarily high values for labor productivity relative to the manufacturing average. But. despite displaying low unit labor costs. petroleum refining recorded large trade deficits in 1967 and 1980. Clearly. demand outweighed supply in the determination of trade flows because of the special position of petroleum in developed economies. T h l n i The high technology industries are defined as industrial chemicals. plastics. electrical machinery. office machinery. turbines. aircraft. and professional goods. 73 The United States held a comparative advantage in the production of industrial chemicals in 1967 and 1980. These sectors are characterized by high labor productivity relative to all manufactures. They were able to maintain their low unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980. with the agricultural chemical industry improving its ranking. Because of low unit labor costs. industrial chemical industries registered trade surpluses in 1967 and 1980. Due to a decline in its unit labor costs. agricultural chemicals significantly increased its trade surplus. The United States held a comparative advantage in the manufacture of plastics in 1967 and 1980. This strong ranking is attributable to the high level of labor productivity in plastics relative to all manufactures. The industry sustained trade surpluses in both years because of low unit labor costs. With reductions in labor compensation. the plastics industry was able to decrease its relative unit labor costs and increase its trade surplus in 1980. In 1967 and 1980. the United States held a comparative advantage in the manufacture of office and computing equipment and engines and turbines had moderate unit labor costs. These industries possessed high levels of labor productivity relative to the manufacturing average. In addition. each was able to decrease its unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980. Although trade data were not available for the office and computing equipment industry. the turbine industry registered a trade surplus in 1967 and 1980. With reductions in its cost structure. it was able to improve its 74 trade position in 1980. The electrical machinery industry encompasses products with varied unit labor costs. These are moderate in electrical distributing. industrial equipment. communications equipment. and electronic components. low for radio and TLV. receiving equipment. All were able to reduce unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980. Except for radio and T.V. equipment. the United States recorded a trade surplus in electrical machinery for 1967 and 1980. In conformity with the comparative costs theory. all industries except for the one noted. were able to improve their trade surpluses. In 1967. the United States held a comparative disadvantage in manufacture of aircraft. The low ranking was caused by the high labor compensation relative to the nanufacturing average. By 1980. aircraft reduced their unit labor costs with significant decreases in relative labor compensation and productivity. Although aircraft registered a surplus in 1967. trade data was not available for 1980. ‘thus further conclusions are not possible at present. The United States possessed a comparative advantage in 'the production of professional goods. The exception was Uneasuring and controlling instruments industry. which ranked 99 by unit labor costs. The high levels of labor ilroductivity contributed to the strong ranking of these industries. This ranking was preserved from 1967 to 1980. \Nith the engineering. scientific. medical. and optical H1struments industries reducing their unit labor costs. 75 Professional goods registered a trade surplus in 1980. With reductions in their unit labor costs. the optical and medical instruments industries were able to improve their trade positions. Conchgign The statistical results indicated that unit labor costs were an important factor in explaining the trade flows of the United States during the two years examined. Although theR2 was low'inlall regressions. the coefficients were significant and had the correct sign. The results of the rankings by unit labor costs for 1967 and 1980 indicated that the United States held a comparative advantage in manufacture of agricultural manufacturing products. paper products. nonferrous metals. publishing. industrial chemicals. plastics. office and computing equipment. and professional goods. The United States held a comparative disadvantage in traditional low technology products. wood products. furniture. pottery. glass. rubber. iron and steel. and most transport equipment. Iron and steel. rubber. and transport were the only industries to decline significantly in ranking from 1967 to 1980. This was reflected in the large trade deficits they incurred. In contrast. the aircraft. agricultural chemicals. and professional goods industries decreased their unit labor costs and resulted in improvements in their trade position. But all industries did not conform to comparative cost theory. The trade position of some industries was not 76 affected by supply but instead dominated by demand factors. trade restrictions. and transportation costs. Nevertheless. supply considerations did explain a large portion of the trade flows. CHAPTER V CROSS-SECTIONAL AND TIME SERIES EVIDENCE FOR THE UNITED STATES. JAPAN. AND EUROPE This chapter investigates the effect of unit labor costs on trade flows for the period 1967-1981 in the United States. Japan. and three European countries: Germany. the United Kingdom. and Italy. The first part examines unit labor costs and trade positions of manufacturing industries and develops a cross-sectional model correlating them at two points. 1967 and 1980. The second part analyzes time series data to determine the effect of changes in labor productivity and compensation on the trade performance of individual industries. In addition. all the time series and 'cross-sectional data. combined with dummy variables. are "pooled" into one equation to remove the biases of trade discrimination and exchange rate changes over time on trade performance. The only consistent unit labor cost data available for Japanese and European manufacturing industries are categorized by the three-digit International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC). The ISIC breakdown provides data for 28 manufacturing industries. and it is more aggregated than the SIC breakdown for the United States 77 78 used in the previous chapter. The problems stemming from the aggregation are discussed in the data section. Data German. Japanese. Italian. and British data for labor compensation. value added. and total employees at the three- digit ISIC breakdown were obtained from the United Nations. Yearbogk 9: Industrial Statistics. Italian. British. and German data for 1967 were incomplete. Additional statistics were drawn from the Statistisches Bundesant. Statistisches Jahrbush ffi; gig Bundesregublik Degtschland. Japanese. German. Italian. and British data for export and import values by two- to four-digit Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) breakdown were collected from the United Nations. Commodity Trade Statistics. The OECD exports are from 1:95.18 gy Commogities Market Summaries: Exggrts. series C. All data were rearranged to conform to the three-digit ISIC breakdown. A table of concordance from SITC to ISIC breakdown is provided in the United Nations. Proceedings gfi the ____.United Netioos swarm so Leeds and Less-Jem- Additional information is contained in Farhang Niroomand's thesis: Determinants gt Q3 Strgcture gt i._.i_._&_‘)y Foreign Lag; 1Q Manufactures: 1963-1280. A major problem with the ISIC data is its presentation. Low technology industries. such as glass. leather. and footwear. where trade flows are small (partly because of trade restrictions). are presented in a 79 disaggregated form. The trade restrictions are in the form of tariffs and quotas. which are governed by multi- and bilateral agreements. In contrast. high technology industries. such as machinery and transport equipment. where large trade flows occur. are highly aggregated. For example. the machinery industry consists of such diverse categories as lawn and garden equipment. refrigeration. and laundry equipment. as well as electronic computing equipment. turbines. and oi lfield machinery. Lawn and garden equipment and similar categories employ low to medium technologies. while electronic computing uses high technology. The same problem is true for transport equipment. which consists of such medium technology industries as motor vehicles. ship building. and railroad equipment. as well as the high technology industries of aircraft; guided missiles. and space vehicles. The aggregation of medium and high technology industries makes definitive conclusions impossible because of diverse cost structures. Nevertheless. consistent trends and broad conclusions may still be obtained. Tables 5.1-5.4. presented at the end of the chapter. show unit labor costs and net trade positions of nanufacturing industries in the United States. Japan. and three European countries for 1967 and 1980. The former represents the first year examined in the time series analysis. while the latter is the last year for which ISIC data were available for all the countries. The complete 80 tables. including the breakdown of unit labor costs. are presented in the Appendix. The Cross-Sectional Models This section examines the effect of unit labor costs on trade performance in a cross-sectional model. Four alternative specifications. including the double log form. of the comparative cost model were developed. The use of export shares has been employed in the ”revealed comparative advantage" literature and is used in equations 5.3 and 5.4 as an alternative specification of trade performance. The equations are judged on their ability to generate significant coefficients of the correct sign. and the R2 are not an integral part of the analysis. The equations whose complete results are presented in the Appendix are as follows: (X/N)m s A1n + 111an + 111”: (5.1) log(X/M).n 1: BIn + anlog(L)1n + U2": (5.2) (Xs).n . Cln + can,n + 03"; (5.3) log()(s).n . 01n + D2nlog(L)'n + U4“: (5.4) The additional variables are: Xs - country's share of total OECD exports (exports/total OECD exports): i a industries 3 1.....28: n scountries s 1..”.5 sUnited States.Germany. JapaanHted Kingdom. and Italy. Considering the distorting effects of differential trade restrictions in a cross-sectional model. most of the 81 models performed well. The dependent variable expressed as a ratio between exports and imports. as in equations 5.1 and 5.2. obtained significant coefficients of the correct sign for unit labor costs for the United States. Germany. and Great Britain. Italy generated correct signs. but they were not significant. Japan consistently obtained a positive sign regardless of the specification for 1967 and 1980. with a significant coefficient for I967; The implication is that trade restrictions and demand considerations were more important than supply in explaining trade flows in the two years for Japan. The dependent variable expressed as an industry's export share of total OECD exports. as in equations 5:3 and 5.4. did not perform well. Japan and Germany generated positive coefficients: Italy’s were insignificant. Since only exports were explicitly represented in this variable. import-competing industries are underrepresented. Thus this variable is not as well specified as the ratio of exports to imports. The equations in log linear form did not perform significantly different from the standard form. They do yield elasticities and provide an indication of the responsiveness of a country"s trade flow to changes in unit labor costs. In addition. the Spearman rank correlation coefficients between unit labor cost rankings and export share rankings were estimated. The advantage of nonparametric tests is that they are less restrictive in their assumptions: however. 82 their power is low in comparison with parametric tests. Because of this. the Spearman rank correlations did not provide any additional definitive insights and their results are not reported here. The conclusion is that the examination of unit labor costs provides important information for policy makers who are concerned with the trade balance of a particular industryu That balance'can be improved either by lowering labor compensation or by increasing labor productivity. Time Series Evidence for the United States This section analyzes the effect of changes in labor productivity and compensation cw1LLS. trade performance. The absolute and relative versions of the comparative cost theory are tested in the models below. The absolute version (equations 5.5 and 5.6) correlates changes in the components of unit labor costs with trade performance. By contrast. the relative version (equations 5.7 and 5.8) correlates changes in the components of unit labor costs as a ratio of all manufactures with trade performance. Both versions are estimated in double logarithmic form to obtain elasticities for the explanatory variables. Unit labor cost could not be used as an explanatory variable because it requires too many restrictions on estimation and makes interpretation of the results impossible. 1 Equations 5.7 and 5.8 are closer to the comparative cost theory as reformulated by Kreinin and the g griori 83 expectations are that equations 5.7 and 5.8 wi l l generate more significant coefficients of the correct sign. The equations whose complete results are presented in the Appendix are as follows: (X-M)1t 8 A1: + AZP”: +A3W‘t '1' U1:8 (5.5) log(X/M)‘t = 81. + BZlog(P)‘t + BBlog(W)‘t + U2.: (5.6) C3[W.t/(sumW‘)t] 'i' U3‘3 log[(X/M)‘t/(sumXflsumMfit) 8 01. + (5.8) 021°g[P.t/(sumP.)tl + D3log[W‘t/(sumW‘t/(sumW.)t] + U3‘. The additional variables are: P = labor productivity per employee in each U.S. industry (value added/employee): W = labor compensation per employee in each U.S. industry (total compensation/employee). The additional coefficients are: A2.82 a sensitivity of export performance to changes C2.02 in labor productivity: the expected sign of 82 is positive: A3.83 sensitivity of export performance to changes CB.D3 in labor compensation: the expected sign of B3 is negative. Productivity per employee in each industry is expected to be positively correlated with export performance since increases in productivity improve an industry's ranking by comparative advantage. Compensation per employee is expected to be negatively correlated with export performance because increases in compensation erode an industry's ranking. The magnitudes of the coefficients are interpreted as elasticities and may be useful for policy decisions. B4 In general. equations 5.5 and 5.6 performed poorly. as expected. in explaining U.S. trade performance. Equation 5.5 yielded the expected signs for labor productivity in nine cases. but only three were significant. The expected sign was produced in twelve cases for compensation. half of which were significant. Equation 5.6 yielded the expected signs for labor productivity in twelve cases. five of which were significant. and in eleven cases for compensation. five of which were significant. Both equations general ly produced high st. When estimating relative changes in labor productivity and labor compensation. as in equation 5.7. the results performed markedly better. Equation 5.7 yielded the expected signs for labor productivity in nineteen cases. seven of which were significant. The expected sign was produced in twenty—two cases for compensation. ten of which were significant. The logarithmic form did not perform as well as equation 5.7. but it did yield better results than either of the absolute VEPSIODS. Equation 5.8 yielded the expected signs for labor productivity in half cases. half of which were significant. and in fifteen cases for compensation. seven of which were significant. A statistical problem present in all the equations is the existence of multicol linearity. since labor compensation is a function of labor productivity. these two variables are correlated. Nevertheless. although some individual industry equations were sensitive to multicol linearity and produced inconsistent results. it was not a restricting problem in 85 general. Despite these statistical difficulties. the relative version of the comparative cost theory performed well. Pool ing Models and Time Effects Stryker was one of the first to use a time series approach within a comparative cost framework. His method. in a limited way. solved the problem of trade restriction biases. If these restrictions are constant between periods. changes in trade performance are not influenced by differential trade restrictions among industries. Unfortunately. trade restrictions did change within the period studied. and adjustments had to be made to correct for the distortions. This section attempts to solve the problem with the use of a panel data model. which pools all time series and cross-sectional data along with dummy variables into one equation. The dummy variables portion can correct for distortions over time and thus are cal led time effects in the literature. 2 The time effects variables in the panel data model captures changes in differential trade restrictions among industries and exchange rate changes over time without distorting the relationship between the explanatory variables and trade performance. The importance of time effects in modeling trade flows is illustrated in Figure 5.1 and 5.2. using unit labor costs as an explanatory variable. ceteris ggribus. 86 Figure 5.1. Correlation without Time Effects X/M O / m o .. .. .. -- .. -- .. .. -- .. .. .. .. I l l I l I I W / > O- - -- -- -- / \ Unit Labor Costs \ Figure 5.2. Correlation with Time Effects X/M / ,/ // / // O o -- -- .. .. -.. .. .. t2. -/t1. Unit Labor Costs In time I. X/M :- AB = OE. labor costs a 0A. In time 2. X/M a: AC = 00. unit labor costs a CA. where X/M I: trade performance. t a time periods. 87 If a decrease in trade restrictions or exchange rate occurs in time period 2. trade performance (X/M) would increase from OE to 00 without a change in unit labor costs. If a regression without the time effects (Figure 5.1) were to be estimated. an upward bias would occur in the slope coefficient. If time effects are included (Figure 5.2). a change in trade restrictions would be totally'reflected in a change in the intercept. not the slope. Thus this process would yield a lower slope coefficient. and. as expected. lower trade restrictions would be responsible for the increase in trade performance of OD-OE. The models are: 109mm)”: = 01 + (:2 169(9)“: + 03 16901)”; (5.9) + Q1 v,t + + ij.t + mt: log(X/M)it :- 01 + 0216;;(13)it + (:3169111)it + uzt. (5.10) Theladditional variables and coefficient are: J g t“! 3 lees-’14: V time effects to capture changes in trade discrimination: set of t-I dummy variables. Vit - { 1 if i s t. 0 if i at ): Q = coefficients for the set of dummy variables: adjustment to the intercept term. The panel data models were estimated with OLS. The time effects in equation 5.9 were assumed to be fixed. which is the least restrictive assumption. and the estimates of the coefficient are consistent since t is large. 3 The results for equation 5.9 are as fol lows: 88 logX/M = -3.89 + 1.11 IogP - 0.43 109W - 1.93 VI - 1.72 V2 (0.53) (0.21) (0.40) (0.44) (0.42) - 1.71 V3 - 1.69 V4- 1.50 V5- 1.28 V6- 1.02 V7 (0.41) (0.40) (0.39) (0.38) (0.37) - 1.03 V8 - 0.99 V9 - 0.95 V10 - 0.73 V11 (0.36) (0.35) (0.35) (0.35) - 0.45 V12 - 0.33 V13 - 0.23 V14 (0.34) (0.34) (0.34) (Standard errors in parentheses) R2 = 0.20 F-stat .. 6.45 0-11 stat . 2.75 N . 420. The signs of both the explanatory variables are as expected. but the coefficient for total compensation per employee is not significant at the 95 percent confidence level. In addition. the coefficients of the dummy variables decrease in value over time. One explanation is that trade restrictions havelbecome less influential on'trade flows: the second is that trade flows have trended upward over time.‘4 The results of equations 5.10 without the dummy variables are as fol lows: IOQX/M c - 1.79 + 1.22109P - 0.93 logW (0.33) (0.19) (0.26) R2 s 0.14 F-stat = 34.30 0-w stat . 2.42 N s 420. All the signs were correct. and the explanatory variables are significant. The main difference between equations 5.9 and 5.10 is that W is not significant when dummy variables are included and is significant when they are omitted. One explanation is that wages are correlated with the time trend: since time trends are eliminated with the panel data model. wages become insignificant. Another 89 explanation is that since cross-sectional variations drive the panel data model with time effects. and cross-sectional variations in labor compensation between industries are small. the coefficient would be insignificant. Conclusion The statistical results obtained in this chapter confirm the importance of unit labor costs as a determinant of international trade patterns. The cross-sectional model produced significant results of the correct sign for all the countries except Japan. which generated a positive sign for unit labor costs in 1967 and 1980. For the time series model. correct signs for labor compensation and productivity were produced for two-thirds of the industries when using the relative version of the comparative cost theory. Finally. the panel data model removed the biases of changes in differential trade restrictions and exchange rates and generated positive results based on all available data for the U.S. economy over the period 1967 to 1981. This evidence establishes the importance of considering the performance of unit labor costs in the formation of policy for industries suffering from international competition. In order for an industry to improve its ranking and strengthen its trade position. it must increase labor productivity and decrease compensation. The performance of the unit labor costs of individual industries based on the empirical evidence gathered here is presented in the next chapter. 90 TABLE 5.1 U.S. Unit Labor Costs and Trade Position. 1967 and 1980 INDUSTRY UNIT LABOR COSTS a X—M b 1967 1980 1967 1980 Food Products 0.384 0.377 —376.4 3673.2 Beverages 0.344 0.352 -565.9 -2422.2 Tobacco 0.187 0.220 151.0 1051.7 Textiles 0.536 0.553 -740.4 -1462.7 Wearing Apparel 0.558 0.555 -708.8 -6634.0 Leather and Products 0.570 0.550 -174.7 -984.7 Footwear 0.549 0.515 -260.5 -2763.4 Wood Products 0.574 0.589 -506.6 -817.4 Furniture. Fixtures 0.555 0.569 -76.1 -722.5 Paper and Products 0.455 0.478 -573.6 -985.7 Printing. Publishing 0.498 0.494 184.7 630.2 Industrial Chemicals 0.293 0.461 1665.7 10689.7 Other Chemical Products 0.365 0.279 694.8 2639.1 Petroleum Refineries 0.203 0.158 -626.5 -12952.3 Petroleum. Coal Product 0.368 0.389 N.A. 481.6 Rubber Products 0.483 0.624 -47.0 -992.6 Plastic Products n.e.c. 0.485 0.514 60.1 859.1 Pottery. China. etc. 0.595 0.603 -96.0 —677.6 Glass and Products 0.461 0.573 -7.4 -65.4 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 0.448 0.482 19.1 125.8 Iron and Steel 0.522 0.714 -1519.0 -9475.1 Nonferrous Metals 0.444 0.511 1305.8 -3356.3 Metal Products 0.516 0.565 642.3 2096.3 Machinery n.e.c. 0.511 0.541 4161.6 25205.7 Electrical Machinery 0.526 0.540 445.2 —999.6 Transport Equipment 0.538 0.656 1232.6 -634.3 Professional Goods 0.452 0.456 529.5 2648.6 Other Industries 0.501 0.495 -481.3 -4143.9 0.471 0.543 All Manufactures (a) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added. (b) Units for net trade are millions of dollars. 91 TABLE 5.2 Japanese Unit Labor Costs and Trade Position. 1967 and 1980 INDUSTRY UNIT LABOR COSTS a X-M b 1967 1980 1967 1980 Food Products 0.304 0.336 126.78 -762.69 Beverages 0.198 0.224 -4.13 -206.56 Tobacco 0 0 -6.68 -57.87 Textiles 0.371 0.439 1239.88 2762.71 Wearing Apparel 0.418 0.526 319.65 -1049.07 Leather and Products 0.383 0.456 36.71 0.48 Footwear 0.393 0.463 97.45 -215.23 Wood Products 0.391 0.444 2.48 -7953.21 Furniture. Fixtures 0.427 0.418 16.61 -73.28 Paper and Products 0.320 0.359 -44.54 -716.54 Printing. Publishing 0.375 0.403 -0.24 1.72 Industrial Chemicals 0.187 0.254 234.80 1577.97 Other Chemical Products 0.188 0.193 -161.08 -887.15 Petroleum Refineries 0.109 0.084 -749.39 -6427.01 Petroleum. Coal Products 0.267 0.204 N.A. -12089.54 Rubber Products 0.322 0.391 107.74 1743.82 Plastic Products n.e.c. 0.338 0.370 48.24 117.61 Pottery. China. etc. 0.453 0.466 94.95 517.76 Glass and Products 0.254 0.298 42.40 127.55 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 0.301 0.319 82.78 714.41 Iron and Steel 0.299 0.271 903.31 14560.40 Nonferrous Metals 0.282 0.272 -483.88 -2569.42 Metal Products 0.379 0.407 383.49 3541.10 Machinery n.e.c. 0.359 0.399 308.36 16330.09 Electrical Machinery 0.312 0.372 964.11 19035.22 Transport Equipment 0.316 0.379 1573.19 32114.97 Professional Goods 0.417 0.445 292.51 4749.72 Other Industries 0.355 0.414 546.77 1917.62 All Manufactures 0.319 0.355 (a) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added. (b) Units for net trade are in millions of dollars. 92 TABLE 5.3 German Unit Labor Costs and Trade Performance. 1967 and 1980 INDUSTRY UNIT LABOR COSTS a X-M b 1980 1980 1967 Food Products 0.290 -1696.34 -332.30 Beverages 0.317 -602.36 ~68.30 Tobacco 0.060 247.63 20.98 Textiles 0.641 -898.08 94.97 Wearing Apparel 0.498 -5444.13 -I78.34 Leather. Footwear. etc. 0.534 -2768.74 -83.11 Wood. Furniture. etc. 0.471 -1689.58 -71.50 Paper and Products 0.580 -1847.18 -329.28 Printing. Publishing 0.585 891.65 102.07 Industrial Chemicals 0.538 11004.29 1763.83 Petroleum Refineries 0.061 -10217.00 155.59 Rubber Products 0.592 172.69 47.27 Plastic Products n.e.c. 0.549 645.39 54.24 Pottery. China. etc. 0.441 95.29 48.53_ Glass and Products 0.531 151.27 72.89 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 0.405 270.87 56.94 Iron and Steel 0.519 4818.90 1024.66 Nonferrous Metals 0.824 -1185.28 -445.50 Metal Products 0.626 3230.25 678.89 Machinery n.e.c. 0.625 25470.81 3800.80 Electrical Machinery 0.560 5441.31 1203.89 Transport Equipment 0.578 19460.68 2276.49 Professional Goods 0.461 1784.72 403.80 Other Industries 0.481 -194.74 305.01 All Manufactures 0.495 (a) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added (b) Units for net trade are in millions of dollars. 93 TABLE 5.4 U.K. and Italian Unit Labor Costs and Trade Performance for 1980 INDUSTRY UNIT LABOR COSTS a X-M b U.K ITALY U.K. ITALY Food Products 0.469 0.447 -2452.32 468.18 Beverages 0.303 0.360 1067.11 718.59 Tobacco 0.320 0.749 569.82 -314.65 Textiles 0.704 0.559 -559.71 -51.87 Wearing Apparel 0.729 0.582 -979.32 3786.70 Leather and Products 0.637 0.481 0.13 524.04 Footwear 0.674 0.586 -518.61 3478.14 Wood Products 0.581 0.483 -2208.82 -2075.83 Furniture. Fixtures 0.641 0.493 -101.26 2043.22 Paper and Products 0.594 0.499 -2755.50 -1056.91 Printing. Publishing 0.517 0.570 441.97 427.60 Industrial Chemicals 0.461 0.475 1722.71 -2537.75 Other Chemical Products 0.350 N.A. 3265.02 N.A. Petroleum Refineries 0.082 0.032 85.90 -2890.81 Petroleum. Coal Products 0.361 N.A. -103I.18 N.A. Rubber Products 0.590 0.618 376.53 133.80 Plastic Products n.e.c. 0.551 0.756 -23.15 475.44 Pottery. China. etc. 0.661 N.A. 256.07 N.A. Glass and Products 0.592 N.A. 15.80 N.A. Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 0.392 0.471 39.82 2189.95 Iron and Steel 0.843 0.498 -1074.85 -336.01 Nonferrous Metals 0.584 0.615 -I657.47 -2326.37 Metal Products 0.615 0.543 1044.13 2318.24 Machinery n.e.c. 0.567 0.543 8324.39 6238.49 Electrical Machinery 0.590 0.614 402.01 -109.44 Transport Equipment 0.730 0.638 525.14 -912.72 Professional Goods 0.595 0.541 166.36 -891.99 Other Industries 0.538 0.547 -321.38 1764.24 All Manufactures (a) Unit labor costs are defined as 0.553 compensation/value-added. (b) 0.537 Units for net trade are in millions of dollars. 94 Fggtnotes lIf unit labor costs were to be used in equation 5.5 and EMS, one restriction would applys that the coefficient of W be negative. But in the estimation of 5.7 and 5.8. three restrictions are necessary. causing the expected sign for unit labor costs to be positive and making the results tenuous. 2For more on ”pooling" or panel data models. see Kmenta (1972) and Judge at al. (1980). 3The fixed effects model does not make any specific assumptions about the distribution of the time effects. In addition. correlation between the time effects (changes in exchange rates and differential trade restrictions) and the explanatory variables does not bias the resulted The "within" estimator used in the regression analysis of the panel data with time effects (OLS on P. W. and V) is consistent as n or t becomes large. See Judge at al. (1980. pp. 328-31. 336- 38). ‘The hypothesis that V) = v2 - = v14 can be tested using a joint F test comparing the restricted and unrestricted residual sum of squares. It is obvious in the present case that the hypothesis is rejected. CHAPTER V1 ANALYSIS OF INDUSTRIES This chapter integrates the analysis of Chapter V by examining the performance of unit labor costs for individual manufacturing industries in the United States. Japan. Germany. Italy. and Great Britain. The industries are categorized by low. medium. and high technology. based on U.S. Department of Commerce definitions and similar to the classification used in Chapter IV.1 Each industry’s level of labor productivity. labor compensation. and unit labor costs is examined as a ratio to the manufacturing average for each country. The relative unit labor costs can then be compared between countries to determine comparative advantage. and industries with a comparative advantage are expected to have a trade surplus. Agriculturgl Manufgcturing Tables 5.1-5.4 show that all the countries ranked high by unit labor costs in food products. The LLS. ranking was 7 in 1967 and 5 in 1980. Japan ranked 10 in both 1967 and 1980. during which time its costs of production remained stable. The food products industry in Germany and Italy ranked 3 by unit labor costs in 1980. while Britain ranked 8. From 1967 to 1980. thetLLS. food products industry strengthened its position by increasing labor productivity 95 96 and decreasing compensation relative to all manufactures. In response. the U.S. trade position improved. U.S. food products registered a trade deficit in 1967 but recorded a surplus in 1980. Given the time series evidence in Chapter V. LLS. food products"trade balance is sensitive to changes in unit 'labor costs. The conclusion is that the U.S. food products industry improved its trade balance by reducing its unit labor costs. Each of the countries examined ranked high in the beverage industry category. The LLS. and Japanese industries ranked 4 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 1980. Germany ranked 4 in 1980. while Britain and Italy ranked 2. Still. U.S. beverages registered trade deficits in 1967 and 1980. Although the industry decreased its unit labor costs by increasing relative productivity» its trade position deteriorated between the two periods. The time series evidence suggests that the U.S. beverage industry's trade position was not sensitive to changes in unit labor costs. Thus. demand factors and trade restrictions were responsible for the deterioration in its trade balance. The United States. Germany. and Britain held a comparative advantage in the tobacco industry. The LLS. tobacco industry ranked 1 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 2 in 1980. Germany ranked 1 in 1980. and Britain ranked 3. All of these high rankings due to high productivity levels. resulting in large trade surpluses for each country. In contrast. the Japanese and Italian tobacco industries are 97 very small. Japan ranked last by unit labor costs in both 1967 and 1980. while Italy ranked last in 1980. There was no value added in the Japanese tobacco industry. and the average wage per employee was high relative to the manufacturing average. Traditional Low Technolggy Industries Tables IV-B to VIII-B show'that the traditional low technology industries are characterized by low levels of labor productivity and compensation relative to the manufacturing average within each country. The United States was able to reduce its unit labor costs and improve its ranking in each of the traditional low technology industries because of reductions in labor compensation relative to all manufactures. Nevertheless. neither the United States. Japan. Germany. nor Britain ranked high by unit labor costs in textiles. wearing appanel. or leather. Italy exhibited a comparative advantage in the leather products industry. which ranked 6 in 1980. While no country ranked high in footwear. the United States enjoyed a decided cost advantage. This was primarily because of the low level of compensation in U.S. footwear relative to all manufactures. Although the United States recorded trade deficits in all the traditional low technology industries. performance varied among industries. In textiles. the United States recorded trade deficits in 1967 and 1980. and by keeping its relative unit labor costs stable between the two years. the industry's trade deficit 98 remained constant. U.S. wearing apparel and leather sustained large trade deficits in both 1967 and 1980. In contrast. U.S. footwear registered only a small trade deficit in 1967 but a large one in 1980. Although U.S. wearing apparel. leather. and footwear were able to lower their relative unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980. their trade position deteriorated. Since the trade positions of these sectors did not improve with lower unit labor costs. trade restrictions and demand factors were responsible for the distortion of these industries' trade patterns. Forest Products Tables 5.1-5.4 show that Germany and Italy held a comparative advantage in the manufacture of wood products and furniture. while the United States and Japan displayed a comparative disadvantage. U.S. wood products ranked 27 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 24 in 1980. Japan ranked 22 in 1967 and 1980. The German wood products and furniture industry ranked 8 by unit labor costs in 1980: Britain's ranked 13 and Italy's 7. The strong positions of Germany and Italy in wood products was due to their high labor productivity. Nevertheless. both generated large trade deficits in wood products for 1980 despite their low unit labor costs. But since there is relatively little trade in wood products. changes in its unit labor costs have little effect on trade flows. U.S. wood products sustained trade deficits in 1967 99 and 1980. Despite lowered unit labor costs. the wood products trade balance did not change significantly. Italy held a comparative advantage in the furniture industry. resulting in a trade surplus. In contrast. the United States. Japan. and Britain held a comparative disadvantage. Their high unit labor costs were caused by low labor productivity relative to all manufactures. The U.S. furniture industry ranked 24 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 22 in 1980. Japan ranked 26 in 1967 and 20 in 1980. Britain’s ranked 22 in 1980. and Italy's 8. The furniture industry is characterized by low labor productivity relative to the manufacturing average. The United States. Japan. and Britain had high levels of labor compensation relative)to»productivity. resulting in high unit labor costs. The U.S. furniture industry suffered trade deficits in 1967 and 1980. although the industry was able to lower its relative unit labor costs between 1967 and 1980. its trade position deteriorated over the period. Tables 5.1-5.4 show that the United States displayed a comparative advantage in the paper industry. and because of increased productivity its cost advantage over the other countries widened. The U.S. paper industry ranked 11 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 9 in 1980: Japan ranked 13 in 1967 and 11 in 1980. Germany's industry ranked 18 in 1980. Britain’s 18. and Italy's 16. The U.S. paper industry registered trade deficits in both years despite its comparative advantage. Since relative unit costs were reduced during this period with no improvement in the paper 100 industry”s trade position. demand had to play the major role in determining trade flows. Nonmetal Products Germany and Italy held a comparative advantage in the pottery and china industry. while the United States and Japan had a comparative disadvantage. The U.S. pottery and china industry ranked 28 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 25 in 1980: the comparable figures for Japan were 26 and 27. The industry in Germany ranked 6 in 1980. in Britain 23. and in Italy 4. Although labor productivity in this sector was relatively low in all the countries. German and Italian labor productivity was high relative to its compensation. This resulted in low unit labor costs and a strong trade surplus for both countries. The U.S. pottery and china industry recorded trade deficits in 1967 and 1980. Despite reducing relative unit labor costs between the two years. the pottery industry’s trade position did not improve. Since the industry's trade position was not responsive to supply considerations. demand factors and trade restrictions were the major forces in determining trade flows. Japan displayed a comparative advantage in the glass industry. which ranked 5 in 1967 and 8 in 1980. The high ranking was due to high productivity relative to the manufacturing average. Japan was able to translate its relative cost advantage in glass manufacturing into a strong trade surplus. 101 The U.S. glass industry's unit labor costs increased between 1967 and 1980. thus reducing its ranking from 12 in 1967 to 23 in 1980. The U.S. glass industry recorded trade deficits in both years. and in conformity with the comparative cost theory. its trade position deteriorated. The United States. Japan. Germany. and Britain ranked high in other nonmetal products. U.S. nonmetals ranked 9 by unit labor costs in 1980 and 10 in 1967: for Japan the ranking was 9 in both years: Germany ranked 5 in 1980. Britain 6. U.S. nonmetal products recorded trade surpluses in 1967 and 1980. Since its relative unit labor costs remained stable during this period. the industry”s trade position also remained stable. Medium Technology Industrigg Medium technology manufacturing has been defined as the iron and steel. nonferrous metals. metal products. energy. rubber. transport equipment. and publishing industries. A problem exists with the aggregation of categories. For example. the transport equipment classification consists of medium1and high technology industries. whcin means that only broad conclusions can be drawn. Another problem is the inclusion of the energy classification. dominated by demand factors which lead to extraordinarily high values for labor productivity. thus distorting the analysis. 102 Iron and Steel The U.S. iron and steel industry has experienced increasing pressure from international competition over the past twenty years (Kreinin. 1984). The main factors responsible for the decline in UJL competitiveness were rapid escalation of labor compensation relative to the manufacturing average and slow adaptation of new technologies. leading to declines in relative productivity. Both factors increased iron and steel’s relative unit labor costs. thus reducing its internal ranking and international competitiveness. An indication that new technologies were not adopted in the iron and steel industry are estimates that less than 30 percent of U.S. steel was continuously cast in 1983. vs. 90 percent of Japanese steel. The continuous casting process turns out a single strand of molten metal for simultaneous rol 1 ing. thereby el iminating ingot casting. reheating and trimming. Imported tonnage accounted for 22 percent of total LLS. steel sales in 1982. Although most of this was imported from Japan and Europe. an increasing amount coming from such Third World producers as Brazil. South Korea. Mexico. Taiwan. and Trinidad and Tobago. After European and Japanese producers agreed in 1982 to limit steel exports to the United States. developing countries quickly increased their exports.2 Tables 5.1-5.4 show that Japan and Germany held a comparative advantage in iron and steel production. whi le 103 the United States and Britain had a comparative disadvantage. The U.S. ranked 19 in 1967 and last in 1980: the figures for Japan 8 and 6. Germany ranked 6 in 1980. Britain ranked last. and Italy 9. The Japaness iron and steel industry was able to strengthen its position because of increases in labor productivity while maintaining its wage structure. The U.S. industry. in contrast fel l drastical ly in ranking by unit labor costs. Despite a slight increase in labor productivity. it experienced large increases in labor compensation relative to all manufactures. U.S. iron and steel registered trade deficits in 1967 and 1980. Since its relative unit labor costs increased significantly. its trade position also deteriorated rapidly. Nonferrous Metals An important factor affecting this sector is increasing government ownership of nonferrous metals industries. Over the past decade. the major Third World copper producers -- Chile. Zambia. and Zaire -- have nationalized production. It is estimated that 55 percent of the world's output is now produced by government corporations compared to 33 percent ten years ago. The government enterprises are not motivated by profit but instead are concerned with domestic employment. foreign exchange. and the demands of international lending agencies. They often ignore economic conditions in the copper markets and keep producing in order to maintain employment and foreign exchange. In the process 104 they depress metals prices and export unemployment. The private aluminum industry has also been hurt by high levels of production from government-owned smelters in Venezuela and Bahrain. By 1985. Alcoa estimates that government smelters will account for 50 percent of the industry"s output compared to 15 percent in 1960. Japan held a comparative advantage in the manufacture of nonferrous metals. while Germany and Italy had a comparative disadvantage. U.S. nonferrous metals ranked 8 in 1967 and 13 in 1980: Japan’s ranking was 7 in both years. Germany ranked last in 1980. Britain 14. and Italy 20. Tables V-B and X-B show that Japan widened its advantage in this sector by increasing relative labor productivity and decreasing labor compensation. In the U.S. industry. relative unit labor costs remained stable between 1967 and 1980.1L5u nonferrous metals recorded consistent trade deficits in 1967 and 1980: since unit labor costs did not change. the industry's trade position also remained stable. Metal Products The metal products category is predominantly composed of medium technology industries. except for ordnance. which because of high levels of R30. has been classified as high technology. However. ordnance products constitute a smal 1 share of the overall category and should not bias the results. 105 Although none of the countries ranked high in metal products. the United States and Italy had the lowest relative unit labor costs. thus yielding a comparative advantage. Rankings for the U.S. industry were 18 in 1967 and 21 in 1980. Comparable rankings for Japan were 20 and 18. Germany ranked 22 in 1980. Britain 20. and Italy 12. Tables IV-B and IX-B show that the U.S. metal products industry slightly decreased its unit labor costs by increasing labor productivity and decreasing compensation relative to all manufactures. The U.S. industry registered trade surpluses for 1967 and 1980. Since its relative unit labor costs did not significantly change over the period. its trade position also remained stable. Rubber Products Although no country ranked high in rubber products. the United States. Germany. and Italy displayed a comparative disadvantage. The U.S. industry ranked 13 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 26 in 1980: in Japan. 14 and 15 for these years. Germany ranked 20 in 1980. Britain 16. and Italy 21. Table 5.1 shows that the U.S. rubber industry experienced a significant reduction in ranking by unit labor costs between 1967 and 1980. The causes were the large decreases in productivity per employee and rises in compensation relative to all manufactures. This drop in ranking was reflected in the industry’s trade position. Although there were trade deficits in 1967 and 1980. these had increased by 1980. The higher unit labor costs of the 106 rubber industry were responsible for its trade balance deterioration. Transport Egyipment The transport category is aggregated. consisting of both medium and high technology industries. Since the individual industries in this group are heterogeneous. consistent conclusions about individual ones are impossible. but broad conclusions about the category can still be drawn. The motor vehicle industry has requested trade restrictions to stem the tide of imports from Japan and Europe. In response. the Japanese have extended their "voluntary" limit on U.S. exports through March 1985. The new passenger-car limit. starting April 1. 1984. is 1.85 million vehicles compared to 1.68 million annually the previous three years. which signifies that the U.S. industry will continue to enjoy strong nontariff protection. This resulted in U.S. automotives experiencing high average compensation per employee. poor quality standards. and inefficient plant. However. a slow improvement in international competitiveness may be under way (Kreinin. 1984). Tables 5.1-5.4 show that Japan held a comparative advantage in the manufacture of transport equipment. The U.S. industry ranked 22 in 1967 and 27 in 1980. Japan's rankings were 12 and 14 respectively. Germany ranked 17 in 1980. Britain 27. and Italy 22. Although the U.S. transport industry improved its relative labor productivity. compensation per employee increased even faster. This 107 resulted in higher unit labor costs and a lower ranking: it registered a trade surplus in 1967 and a trade deficit in 1980. consistent with the comparative cost theory. Publighing The United States and Britain displayed a comparative advantage in the printing industries. The LLS. rankings were 15 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 11 in 1967. Comparable Japanese ranking were 19 and 17. The figure for Germany was 19 in 1980. for Britain 9. and for Italy 16. The U.S. printing industry was able to improve its ranking with cuts in labor compensation. The time series evidence suggests that its trade balance was sensitive to changes in unit labor costs. Thus in conformity with comparative cost theory. the U.S. printing industry was able to increase its trade surplus between 1967 and 1980. Energy The energy industries consists of petroleum refining and petroleum and coal products. All the countries studied appeared to exhibit a comparative advantage in this sector. but the category is overwhelmingly dominated by demand factors which distort the analysis. The U.S. petroleum refining industry ranked 2 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 1 in 1980. Japan ranked 1 in both years. Britain and Italy ranked 1 in 1980 and the German petroleum refining and other petroleumland coal products industries ranked 2 by unit labor costs in that year. The United States. Japan. and Germany each recorded trade 108 deficits in the petroleum refining industry for 1980. despite its high ranking. Thus. demand was the primary determinant of trade flows. The United States. Japan. and Britain ranked high in petroleum and coal products. The U.S. ranking by unit labor costs was 6 in both years. Japan ranked 6 in 1967 and 3 in 1980. Britain ranked 5 in 1980. U.S. petroleum and coal products registered a trade deficit in 1967 but a trade surplus in 1980. In conformity with the comparative cost theory. the U.S. industry reduced its relative unit labor costs and improved its trade position. High Technology Industries In the high technology manufacturing category are industrial chemicals. other chemicals. plastics. machinery. electrical machinery. and professional goods. A severe problem with this classification is the aggregation in most of the industries. especially industrial chemicals. machinery. and electrical machinery. They are composed of both medium and high technology industries. which distorts the unit labor costs of the overall category. Ingustrigl Chgmicglg Although the category is highly aggregated. except for industrial organic chemicals (medium technology). the sector employs high technology. Thus. general conclusions can be reached. 109 Tablee.5u1 and 5.2 show that while the United States and Japan have had a comparative advantage in industrial chemicals. Japan’s advantage appears to be disappearing. To obtain stronger conclusions. disaggregated data must be observed for Japan. but unfortunately these have not been published. The U.S. industrial chemical industry ranked 3 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 8 in 1980. Japan ranked 2 in 1967 and 5 in 1980. The German figures. which includes al 1 chemical industries. was a ranking of 14 in 1980 and its wage structure has remained stable since 1967. According to Tables IV-B and IX-B. both the U.S. and Japanese industries increased their relative unit labor costs from 1967 to 1980. This has stemmed from decreases in labor productivity and increases in compensation relative to all manufacturing. Nevertheless. the high technology segment of industrial chemicals. examined in Table 4.1. maintained its costs structure. LLS. industrial chemicals registered trade surpluses.in I967.and 1980.*widening the surplus in the latter year. Other Chemigalg Other chemicals consists of the categories drugs. soap. paints. and miscel laneous chemicals. Aside from the drug industry. this category employs medium technOIOQY. but since drugs are the most important segment. the whole category is included here as a high technology industry. Tables 5.1. 5.2. and 5.4 show that the United States. Japan. and Britain achieved a high ranking in other chemical 110 industries. The U.S. ranking by unit labor costs was 5 in 1967 and 3 in 1980. Japan ranked 3 in 1967 and 2 in 1980. Britain ranked 4 in 1980. Although Japan’s other chemicals kept unit labor costs constant between 1967 and 1980. the 0.5. industry decreased unit labor costs substantial ly. This drop was owing to large increases in labor productivity and decreases in compensation relative to the manufacturing average. U.S. other chemicals registered trade surpluses in 1967 and 1980. By reducing unit labor costs. the industry": trade position improved between the two years in conformity with the comparative cost theory. Plastics The plastics industry is characterized by low labor productivity relative to all manufactures within each country. While no country ranked high in plastics. the United States held a comparative advantage and Italy a comparative disadvantage. U.S. plastics ranked 14 in 1967 and 1980: Japan ranked 15 in 1967 and 12 in 1980. Germany ranked 15. Britain 11. and Italy last in 1980. Tables IV-B and IX-B show that LLS. plastics decreased unit labor costs between 1967 and 1980 by decreasing compensation per employee relative to the manufacturing average. Since the U.S. industry also registered trade surpluses in both years. the improvement in its trade position conforms with the comparative cost theory. Machinery The aggregated machinery category consists of both medium and high technology industries. The former farm and garden. metalworking. and refrigeration machinery. The latter are engines and turbines. construction. and office and computing machinery. However. even the last segment is not homogeneous. containing medium technology calculating and accounting machines and typewriters as well as high- speed computers. Thus. consistent conclusions are impossible to reach about the individual industries. Although neither the United States nor Japan held a clear comparative advantage in the machinery industry. Germany had a clear comparative disadvantage. This was due to Germany's low level of productivity and high level of compensation relative to al 1 manufactures. U.S. machinery ranked 17 by unit labor costs in both 1967 and 1980: Japan ranked 16 in 1980 and 17 in 1967. Germany ranked 21 in 1980. Britain and Italy 12. The U.S. machinery industry decreased its unit labor costs between 1967 and 1980. This was achieved by increases in labor productivity and decreases in compensation in comparison to al I manufactures. The industry registered a small trade surplus in 1967 and a large one in 1980. By reducing unit labor costs. the machinery industry"s trade position improved over the period in conformity with the comparative cost theory. 112 Electrical Machinery The highly aggregated electrical machinery category consists of medium and high technology industries. The former are household appliances. electrical lighting. and radio and TV receiving equipment. The latter are electrical distributing and communication equipment and electronic components” The dichotomy'within this sector makes strong conclusions impossible. None of the countries ranked high in electrical machinery. although the United States had the lowest unit labor costs. thus yielding a comparative advantage.lLS. electrical machinery ranked 20 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 16 in 1980: Japan ranked 11 in 1967 and 13 in 1980. Germany ranked 16 in 1980. Britain 15. and Italy 19. In U.S. electrical machinery. unit labor costs decreased between 1967 and 1980 owing to increased labor productivity and decreased compensation relative to all manufactures. Nevertheless. the trade surplus in 1967 had changed to a deficit by 1980. Although the U.S. industry lowered relative unit labor costs between the two years. its trade position deteriorated. Since supply factors improved. demand factors were responsible. Prof sio al s The professional goods category consists primarily of engineering and scientific devices and medical instruments. With few exceptions. the entire category'is classified as high technology. 113 Tables 5.1-5.3 show that the United States and Germany held a comparative advantage in the manufacture of professional goods while Japan had a comparative disadvantage. U;S. professional goods ranked 10 by unit labor costs in 1967 and 7 in 1980. The respective Japanese rankings were 24 and 23. Germany ranked 7 in 1980. Britain 19. and Italy 11. The strong U.S. position stems from high levels of relative labor productivity. whereas Germany’s is derived from low relative compensation levels. Japan. in contrast. displayed very low levels of labor productivity relative to compensation. The U.S. professional goods industry decreased unit labor costs between 1967 and 1980 with large increases in labor productivity and moderate decreases in compensation relative to all manufactures. The UJL industry recorded trade surpluses in both years and. by moving up in ranking. was able to improve its trade position over the period. in conformity with the comparative cost theory. Summary The analyses of individual industries indicates that in 1967 and 1980. the United States held a comparative advantage in the manufacture of food‘products. tobacco. paper. printing. industrial chemicals. plastics. and professional goods. It held a comparative disadvantage in iron and steel. rubber. transport equipment. wood products. and glass. The industries which experienced a reduction in international competitiveness between 1967 and 1980 were 114 iron and steel. transport equipment. glass. and rubber. In 1967 and 1980. Japan held a comparative advantage in glass. iron and steel. nonferrous metals. transport equipment. and industrial chemicals: a comparative disadvantage in tobacco. food products. traditional ly low technology products. and professional goods. Japan’s comparative advantage remained relatively stable between 1967 and 1980. In 1980. Germany held a comparative advantage in tobacco. food products. wood products. pottery. and professional goods: a comparative disadvantage in paper. nonferrous products. metal products. rubber. industrial chemicals. and machinery. In 1980. Italy held a comparative advantage in leather. forest products. and pottery. It displayed a comparative disadvantage in tobacco. nonferrous metals. rubber. plastics. and electrical machinery. In 1980. Britain held a comparative advantage in industrial chemicals. plastics. tobacco. printing. and other nonmetal products. Its comparative disadvantage lay in wearing apparel. furniture. pottery and china. iron and steel. and transport equipment. Knowledge of a country's comparative advantage at a particular time and of the changes over time are useful to a policy maker. In order for an industry whose ranking is low and which is suffering from a trade deficit to improve its position. it must decrease unit labor costs by reducing labor compensation. increasing productivity. or both. 115 Although all industries do not respond quickly to changes in supply. these do explain a large portion of trade flows and must be considered in the formulation of international policy decisions. 1 16 Footnotes 1For a detailed breakdown of industry categories see Davis (1982). Kelly (1977). and Boretsky (1982). all from the U.S. Department of Commerce. 2Background material for the medium and high technology industries was obtained from Forbes. January 1984. CHAPTER VII CONCLUSION The purpose of this dissertation was to investigate the comparative cost advantage of manufacturing industries in the United States. Japan. and Europe between 1967 and 1980. Since it was not possible to derive accurately all the costs of production. the internal ranking of industries by comparative advantage was'approximated using the inverse of unit labor cost and its components. labor productivity and labor compensation. Although most relevant studies have measured an industry"s unit labor costs across countries at one time. they were limited in scope and subject to distortions stemming from deviations in the long-run equilibrium exchange rate. The distortions can be corrected for in an approach. developed by Viner and Kreinin. which examines an industry’s unit labor costs relative to the national manufacturing average. Thisiallows all commodities produced by a country to be ranked internally by their domestic unit labor costs. Each country'would export the commodities in which its comparative cost advantage is the greatest and import those ranking the lowest (highest production costs). with the exchange rate separating the two. Thus. comparative cost advantages "are embedded in the total economy” and 117 118 become an effective tool on which to base policy decisions (Kreinin. 1984. p. 42). Increases in an industry’s unit labor costs relative to the manufacturing average reduce its internal ranking and international competitiveness. Since comparative advantage is important to the determination of trade flows. and in light of the large U.S. current account deficits registered recently. industries subject to acute import competition can alleviate their situation by decreasing unit labor costs. Therefore. increasing labor productivity. decreasing labor compensation. or both. become important to improving internal ranking and strengthening an industryms trade position without relying on trade restrictions. The theoretical foundations of the classical comparative cost model were developed beginning with the Ricardian hypothesis. The assumptions of the latter were relaxed with the introduction of money wages. a multicommodity framework. transportation costs. and incomplete specialization to construct a more realistic model. It was demonstrated that the sharp distinction drawn between the Ricardian and Heckscher-Ohlin theories disappeared with the relaxation of the assumptions. The differences between countries in comparative labor productivities that were asserted by assumption in the Ricardian hypothesis were deduced from differences in relative factor endowments in the Heckscher-Ohlin model. Therefore. these two theories do not provide conflicting viewpoints. but instead are interdependent and are both 119 important to understanding international trade flows. MacDougall. Balassa. Stern. and Stryker's empirical results confirmed the comparative cost theony. MacDougall found a strong inverse relationship between 1937 relative U.S. and U.K. wage costs per unit of output and relative exports and a positive relationship between relative output per worker and relative exports. Balassa and Stern's results indicated that the 1950 relative U.S. and U.K. export performance followed established lines of comparative advantage as suggested by labor productivity. The introduction of differences in capital costs per unit of output did not have any significant effect on export performance. Stryker's time series evidence suggested that changes in U.S. and Canadian exports were correlated with changes in labor productivity and that the latter is a useful proxy for total factor productivity. In contrast. Bhagwati. Stern. and Kreinin concluded that their empirical evidence did not support the simple Ricardian hypothesis. and that other factors were important in determining the pattern of trade. Although Bhagwati's tests produced a poor fit between 1950 relative labor productivity and price ratios and the relationship between comparative unit labor costs and export price ratios. the variables were measured inconsistently. Thus. as Daly stated. failures to establish a correlation between export price ratios and labor productivity ratios stem from the lack of conceptual and statistical compatibility in the data 120 rather than provide evidence against the Ricardian hypothesis. The statistical results in this dissertation generated from the cross-sectional and time series data confirmed the importance of unit labor costs as a determinant of international trade patterns. With the exception of Japan. which generated a positive sign for unit labor costs in 1967 and 1980. the coefficients generated by the cross-sectional models were significant and of the correct sign. The coefficient regressions from these equations were low. which was not unexpected considering the multitude of factors affecting international trade. For the time series model. correct signs for labor compensation and productivity were produced for most of the industries when using the relative version of the comparative cost theory. Finally. the panel data model removed the biases of changes in differential trade restrictions and exchange rates and generated positive results based on all available data for the U.S. economy over the period 1967 to 1981. Thus. the empirical evidence reveals that unit labor costs are an important determinant of international trade flows and must be considered in the development of policy for industries suffering from import ,competition. The results for 1967 and 1980 indicated that the United States held a comparative advantage. as approximated by unit labor costs. in the following industries: agricultural manufacturing. paper. nonferrous metals. publishing. 121 industrial chemicals. plastics. office and computing equipment. and professional goods. It held a comparative disadvantage in traditional low technology products. wood products. furniture. pottery. glass. rubber. iron and steel. and most transport equipment. The three major industries in the UAL economy which experienced a reduction in international competition between 1967 and 1980 were iron and steel. transport. and rubber. It was seen that these significantly increased their unit labor costs relative to other manufactures. causing them to fall sharply in the internal ranking. This was reflected in the large trade deficits they incurred.1ricontrast. the iron and steel. transport and rubber industries in Japan and Germany were able to maintain their internal ranking. Thus. the increases in international competition for these industries resulted from changes in unit labor costs within the United States and not from the extraordinary performance of foreign competitors. In contrast. the aircraft. agricultural chemicals. and professional goods industries decreased their unit labor costs. which improved their trade position. But all industries did not conform to comparative cost theory. The trade position of some industries was not effected by supply but instead dominated by demand factors. trade restrictions. and transportation costs. Nevertheless. supply considerations did explain a large portion of the trade flows. 122 In 1967 and 1980. Japan held a comparative advantage in glass. iron and steel. nonferrous metals. transport equipment. and industrial chemicals: a comparative disadvantage in tobacco. food products. traditional ly low technology products. and professional goods. Japan’s comparative advantage remained relatively stable between 1967 and 1980. In 1980. Germany held a comparative advantage in tobacco. food products. wood products. pottery. and professional goods: a comparative disadvantage in paper. nonferrous products. metal products. rubber. industrial chemicals. and machineryu Italy held a comparative advantage in leather. forest products. and pottery. It displayed a comparative disadvantage in tobacco. nonferrous metals. rubber. plastics. and electrical machinery. Great Britain held a comparative advantage in industrial chemicals. plastics. tobacco. printing.iand other nonmetal products. Its comparative disadvantage lay in wearing apparel. furniture. pottery and china. iron and steel. and transport equipment. This evidence establishes the importance of considering unit labor costs in the formation of policy for industries experiencing international competition. Knowledge of a countrst comparative advantage at a particular time and the rate of its change are useful to policy makers. An industry ‘with low ranking which is suffering from a trade deficit can strengthen its position through decreased unit labor costs: by reducing labor compensation. increasing productivity. or 123 both. Thus. internal responses to international competition are vital. without reliance on trade restrictions. to solving an industry's trade problems. APPENDIX A TABLE I-A Concordance Between the Three-Digit International Standard Industrial Classification (top number) and the U.S. Standard Industrial Classification 311/2 313 314 321 322 323 324 201 2082 21 22 2311 3111 3131 202 2083 239 232 3151 314 203 2084 233 3161 204 2085 234 317 205 2086 235 3199 206 236 207 2371 2087 209 331 332 341 342 351 352 353 24 25 26 27 281 283 2911 282 284 286 2851 287 289 354 355 356 361 362 369 371 295 3011 3079 326 3211 3241 331 299 3021 322 325 332 3031 3231 327 3041 3281 3069 329 372 381 382 383 384 385 390 333 34 35 36 37 38 39 3341 335 336 339 124 125 TABLE II-A Concordance Between the 1980 Three-Digit International Standard Industrial Classification (top number) and the Standard International Trade Classification 311/2 313 314 321 322 323 324 012 11 122 26 84 61 851 014 65 831 035 037 046 331 332 341 342 351 352 047 ------------------------------ 048 24 821 251 892 51 53 056 63 64 52 541 058 562 55 061.2 58 572 062 591 598 071.2 592 072 073 353 354 355 356 361 362 091 ------------------------------ 098 334 32 233 893 666 664 335 62 665 341 369 371 372 381 382 383 384 661 67 68 69 71 76 78 662 72 77 79 663 73 667 74 75 385 390 87 894 88 895 896 897 898 126 TABLE III-A Concordance Between the 1967 Three-Digit International Standard Industrial Classification (top number) and the Standard International Trade Classification 311/2 313 314 321 322 323 324 012 11 122 266 84 61 851 013 267 831 032 65 046 047 331 332 341 342 351 352 048 ------------------------------ 052 243 821 251 892 51 53 053 63 64 521 541 055 561 55 062 581 571 071.3 599 072.2 072.3 353/4 355 356 361 362 369 073 ------------------------------ 091 321 231.2 893 666 664 661 099 332 231.3 665 662 341 231.4 663 62 371 372 381 382 383 384 385 67 68 69 71 72 73 B6 812 390 891 894 895 896 897 127 TABLE IV-A OLS Results from Equation 5.1 Country A1 42 R2 N o-w U.S. 1980 5.67 -8.42 0.25 27 1.50 (1.49) (2.91) 1967 17.14 -27.70 0.18 27 1.13 (6.18) (11.70) Japan 1980 1.956 5.186» 0.008 26 1.93 (4.534) (12.038) 1967 -43.80 168.45 0.21 25 1.99 (23.55) (69.02) Germany 1980 1.72 -0.66 0.013 23 1.64 (0.64) (1.22) Britain 1980 3.2694 -0.0035 0.19 27 2.05 (0.0480) (0.0015) Italy 1980 4.19 -1.41 0.0005 23 2.54 (7.75) (13.89) Country 128 TABLE V-A 0L5 Results for Equation 5.2 BI 82 N D-W U05. 1980 -I.68 -1.96 0.19 27 1.92 (0.62) (0.80) 1967 -2.17 -2.80 0.26 27 1.55 (0.72) (0.94) Japan 1980 1.63 1.29 0.04 26 1.29 (1.39) (1.30) 1967 5.41 3.57 0.33 25 2.13 (1.22) (1.06) Germany 1980 ~0.036 -0.219 0.03 23 1.07 (0.264) (0.294) Britain 1980 6.70 -1.07 0.12 27 1.72 (3.70) (0.57) Italy 1980 -0.86 -1.99 0.05 23 2.93 (1.82) 129 TABLE VI-A OLS Results for Equation 5.3 Country 1 C1 C2 R2 N D-W U.S. 1980 31.36 -38.94 0.15 27 1.89 (9.59) (18.73) 1967 47.54 -51.44 0.16 26 2.15 (12.65) (24.05) Japan 1980 0.027 0.173 0.03 26 1.55 (0.072) (0.191) 1967 -0.062 0.483 0.20 25 1.83 (0.068) (0.200) Germany 1980 8.51 12.48 0.15 23 1.79 (3.42) (6.46) Britain 1980 0.2432 -0.00025 0.27 27 1.93 (0.0480) (8.31'10-8) Italy 1980 14.82 -7.64 0.004 23 1.88 (14.89) (26.69) 130 TABLE VII-A OLS Results for Equation 5.4 Country DI 02 R2 N D-W U.S. 1980 -1.23 -2.60 0.03 27 0.43 (2.23) (2.87) 1967 -9.45 -0.93 0.08 26 2.15 (0.50) (0.66) Japan 1980 -2.15 0.73 0.03 26 1.13 (0.86) (0.80) 1967 —0.34 2.06 0.26 25 1.57 (0.84) (0.73) Germany 1980 2.82 0.24 0.11 23 1.73 (0.13) (0.15) Britain 1980 4.08 -1.04 0.17 27 1.82 (2.91) (0.46) Italy 1980 0.88 -1.72 0.08 23 2.16 (0.82) (1.29) 131 TABLE VI 1 I-A OLS Results for Equation 5.5 Industry 41 42 43 R2 D-W Food Products -4I49.71 -339.19 1270.63 0.86 0.78 (996.34) (267.61) (756.31) Beverages 226.42 -67.53 82.95 0.98 2.57 (78.99) (19.23) (55.29) Tobacco -222.51 7.16 20.17 0.99 1.19 (24.11) (3.27) (13.80) Textiles ~641.90 -136.69 202.70 0.38 1.23 (217.01) (252.84) (457.33) Wearing 3580.20 ~408.05 ~236.83 0.99 1.84 Apparel (510.70) (245.87) (499.43) Leather and 413.16 -20.03 -62.81 0.91 1.54 Products (175.36) (67.28) (134.31) Footwear 2177.28 134.72 -691.61 0.95 0.99 (301.67) (99.75) (206.47) Wood Products -80.71 -248.17 378.07 0.50 1.56 (325886) (87.83) (157.88) Furniture. 468.96 61.14 -I92.84 0.94 1.36 Fixtures (105.93) (75.70) (139.60) Paper and -38.78 65.45 -I91.20 0.44 1.40 Products (272.49) (67.76) (149.00) Printing. 240.45 109.83 -210.72 0.87 1.06 Publishing (134.03) (35.18) (78.09) Industrial -3483.81 1.37 455.38 0.87 0.97 Chemicals (929.97) (104.58) (445.74) Other Chemical -266.14 85.33 -190.29 0.90 1.31 Products (268.14) (205.99) (73.19) I32 Petroleum Refineries Petroleum. Coal Products Rubber Products Plastic Products. n.e.c. Pottery. China. etc. Glass and Products Nonmetal Products Iron and Steel Nonferrous Metals Metal Products Machinery n.e.c. Electrical Machinery Transport Equipment Professional Goods Other Industries 3498.82 (1693.00) - 235.21 (22.78) 473.44 (222.53) -522.65 (85.41) 223.38 (16.11) 112.80 (134.97) -108.75 2998.99 (837.11) (659.78) (327.66) -10564.53 (2985.61) ~200.7B (870.77) 3068.32 (1393.00) -934.97 (264.60) 902.34 (640.24) -9.74 (22.53) 0.32 (3.27) 24.41 (50.96) -45.35 (38.79) -28.83 -10.40 (47.08) -48.85 (30.82) -I79.45 (181.76) -15.66 (113.52) -66.27 (195.47) -1130.88 (999.07) (301.03) -605.89 (407.95) -93.33 (96.98) (218.42) -386.74 (184.00) 26.64 (8.48) ~121.96 (84.20) 164.04 (78.96) -3.07 (19.05) 12.82 (79.49) 106.81 (66.18) -78.93 -64.82 (221.97) 218.33 (358.31) 3522.94 (1988.64) 732.75 (590.86) 791.54 (617.71) 372.69 (222.35) 519.13 (484.34) 0.86 0.97 0.76 0.89 0.997 0.06 0.89 0.31 0.70 0.95 0.33 0.35 0.91 0.92 1.51 1.14 0.91 0.91 2.16 0.98 1.94 1.97 1.24 0.91 1.46 1.33 1.49 0.87 133 TABLE IX-A OLS Results for Equation 5.6 Industry 81 82 83 R2 Food Products 0.043 -I.836 2.532 0.88 (0.529) (0.832) (0.937) Beverages -3.344 -2.737 3.975 0.94 (1.139) (1.299) (1.361) Tobacco -2.703 3.534 -3.590 0.35 (3.038) (1.864) (1.782) Texti les -2.485 0.474 0.430 0.68 (2.022) (4.365) (4.562) Wearing -1.301 —2.562 2.897 0.06 Apparel (0.865) (2.995) (3.452) Leather and -2.162 0.714 -0.463 0.25 Products (0.563) (1.995) (2.313) Footwear -5.482 6.159 -6.829 0.71 (0.734) (2.092) (2.391) Wood Products -0.785 -1.009 1.424 0.40 (0.534) (0.857) (0.904) Fixtures (2.278) (5.655) (6.026) Paper and -1.503 0.981 -0.816 0.48 Products (0.378) (0.622) (0.680) Printing. -0.579 7.093 -8.467 0.71 Publishing (0.633) (1.926) (2.195) Industrial 1.547 -0.044 -0.158 0.26 Chemicals (0.646) (0.634) (0.691) Other Chemical 2.318 0.121 -0.628 0.76 Products (1.940) (1.650) (1.606) 1.13 0.89 0.72 1.27 0.65 134 Petroleum Refineries Petroleum. Coal Products Rubber Products Plastic Products. n.e.c. Pottery. China. etc. Glass and Products Nonmetal Products Iron and Steel Nonferrous Metals Metal Products Machinery n.e.c. Electrical Machinery Transport Equipment Professional Goods Other Industries 0.941 (0.838) 15.187 (5.453) 1.823 (1.558) -0.169 (0.898) -I.038 (0.659) 2.443 (2.822) 0.535 (1.187) 0.908 (1.631) -3.128 (2.482) 1.267 (0.866) 2.387 (0.519) 1.079 (0.614) 1.992 (0.835) 2.334 (0.627) -0.404 (0.783) 0.344 (0.748) -3.910 (1.790) -1.203 (1.896) -0.365 (1.457) -2.319 (2.082) -2.642 (3.281) 0.112 (1.706) -0.820 (2.167) 0.168 (3.099) 0.570 (1.919) -1.014 (1.459) (1.793) -2.088 (1.246) -I.270 (0.942) -0.412 (2.134) -1.381 (1.154) 1.867 (1.306) 0.477 (1.785) 0.701 (1.538) 2.486 (2.232) 2.382 (3.006) -0.295 (1.710) 0.248 (1.980) 0.589 (3.216) -1.018 (2.018) 0.736 (1.606) 1.353 (1.990) 1.752 (1.187) 0.961 (0.989) 0.397 (2.428) 0044 0.63 0.39 0.27 0.09 0.05 0.26 0.62 0.31 0.41 0.74 0.04 0.56 1.87 0.89 0.81 0.77 0.68 0.90 1.51 1.08 0.85 0.56 0.99 1.27 0.88 135 TABLE X-A OLS Results for Equation 5.7 industry ' c1 02 03 R2 o-w Food Products 5603.59 697.50 -7112.52 0.54 1.84 (1733.79) (524.27) (1921.69) Beverages 324.53 -373.39 182.94 0.13 1.45 (504.04) (302.13) (585.72) Tobacco -0.22 0.72 -1.41 0.31 2.15' (0.28) (0.35) (0.64) Textiles 6.13 10.90 -IB.58 0.17 2.03” (4.30) (9.81) (13.17) Wearing 0.56 12.81 -12.12 0.06 2.16" Apparel (2.55) (19.64) (15.54) Leather and -92.98 -288.59 377.41 0.20 1.41 Products (101.03) (376.23) (266.18) Footwear 0.40 -6.70 5.07 0.22 1.80“ (0.88) (4.01) (3.86) Wood Products -40.67 238.26 -166.52 0.29 1.58 (296.46) (175.14) (509.90) Furniture. -0.16 -2.32 2.21 0.04 1.78“ Fixtures (0.74) (3.58) (3.80) Paper and 480.29 -7.40 -448.75 0.17 1.35 Products (314.67) (127.95) (333.61) Printing. 38.34 294.83 -317.82 0.32 1.52 Publishing (85.49) (231.70) (166.90) Industrial 3.24 -1.58 0.73 0.05 1.91' Chemicals (6.63) (3.01) (8.76) Other Chemical -0.31 2.74 -4.59 0.13 1.64“ Products (2.14) (9.76) (9.55) Petroleum Refineries Petroleum. Coal Products Rubber Products Plastic Products Pottery. China. etc. Glass and Products Nonmetal Products Iron and Steel Nonferrous Metals Metal Products Machinery n.e.c. Electrical Machinery Transport Equipment Professional Goods Other Industries 136 12.73 0.94 (6.55) (0.46) 0.42 -0.05 (0.29) (0.13) 10.93 1.23 (161.85) (109.03) 199.37 -106.81 (176.20) (232.80) 52.52 222.11 (I49.78) (371.85) 15.53 1.83 (21.54) (10.49) 92.72 -58.37 (58.06) (29.94) 58.52 1137.40 (1231.77) (1181.25) 1133.59 308.69 (806.62) (270.24) -0.41 4.86 (7.14) (7.43) 1707.37 14531.67 (13323.14) (7505.40) -1.44 0.86 (1.62) (1.77) -0.13 2.75 (1.88) (1.33) 589.28 614.49 (774.54) (501.88) 2.01 3.81 (3.11) ' Sample size =196B-1981 -10.64 (5.22) -0032 (0.27) -16.79 (184.21) -127.83 (353.45) -245.25 (372.37) -16.80 (13.78) -33.62 (66.40) -953.88 (579.30) -1301.57 (683.24) -3.80 (11.38) -14412.98 (12273.64) 0.75 (1.57) -3096 (1.03) -1217.16 (1065.93) -6.29 (6.03) 0.16 0.34 0.20 0.27 0.05 0.25 0.08 0.39 0.12 1.40” 2.42* 1.07 1.39 1.00 1.99’ 1.50. 1.17 2.07“ 137 TABLE X I -A OLS Results for Equation 5.8 industry 01 02 03 R2 D-W Food Products -1.70 2.84 -12.56 0.37 0.77 (0.66) (1.82) (5.31) Beverages -2.76 -3.54 17.63 0.83 1.60 (0.53) (1.70) (2.45) Tobacco 1.62 1.04 —1.25 0.10 1.04 (1.57) (1.97) (1.42) Texti les -7.15 -4.55 -9.50 0.89 1.63 (0.65) (2.93) (4.38) Wearing -2.14 -0.10 0.02 0.002 1.22 Apparel (0.49) (1.56) (1.34) Leather and -2.44 -I.39 -0.92 0.44 1.25 Products (0.52) (1.62) (1.35) Footwear -3.70 2.24 -3.27 0.29 0.96 (0.50) (1.40) (1.52) Wood Products 0.90 -2.73 9.21 0.22 0.99 (0.85) (1.55) (5.13) Furniture. -1.59 3.30 -6.36 0.28 0.50 Fixtures (0.61) (4.04) (4.74) Paper and -0.79 1.20 4.78 0.50 0.67 Products (0.13) (0.88) (2.24) Printing. 0.86 3.41 -I.27 0.42 1.73 Publishing (0.11) (1.77) (1.32) Industrial 1.50 -0.43 -0.62 0.22 1.01 Chemicals (0.56) (0.76) (0.99) Other Chemical -2.05 3.88 4.36 0.58 1.40 Products (0.86) (1.43) (3.65) Refineries (3.37) (0.75) (0.80) -" Petroleum, Coal Products Rubber Products Plastic Products. n.e.c. Pottery. China. etc. Glass and Products Non-metal Products Iron and Steel Nonferrous Metals Metal Products Machinery n.e.c. Electrical Machinery Transport Equipment Professional Goods Other Industries 3.99 (1.18) -0.75 (0.17) -0.27 (0.30) -1.58 (0.30) 0.12 (0.15) -0.13 (0.09) -0.36 (0.45) -3.74 (1.14) 0.39 -0.01 (0.25) ‘0.17 (0.13) 0.50 (0.18) 0.51 (0.07) -1.14 (0.46) 138 -3.60 (3.25) 1.77 (1.08) 0.35 (1.80) 0.91 (0.64) -1.61 (1.92) 1.53 (1.87) 0.52 (2.42) 0.65 (3.05) 1.46 (1.96) -3074 (1.15) -I.43 (1.13) -0.46 (0.60) -0.55 (0.95) -1.96 (2.11) -0.62 (5.58) 1.19 (1.98) -3076 (2.77) 0.10 (0.07) -0.22 (2.70) -3090 (4.05) -2.30 (1.50) 19.00 (8.01) 5.40 (3.35) 9.35 2.13 (1.15) -1.46 (0.57) 3.69 (1.86) 0.65 (1.54) 0.11 0.34 0.27 0.25 0.06 0.08 0.17 0.33 0.66 0.66 0.94 0.77 0.92 2.62 0.56 1.26 1.34 1.33 1.16 1.33 APPENDIX 8 TABLE I-B Classification of Two-. Three-. and Four-Digit SIC Manufacturing Industries Into Low. Medium. and High Technology Categories Low Technology Inggstries 20 - 26. 31. 32. 39 Medium Technolggy Industries 27. 284. 2851. 286. 289. 29. 30. 33. 341-347. 349. 352-356. 358. 359. 363. 364. 369. 371. 372. 3743. 3751. 379 filgh Technology Inggstries 281-283. 287. 348. 351. 357. 361. 362. 365-367. 372. 376. 38 This classification system is based on 1L5. Department of Commerce publications. There are no classification systems which can truely capture an industry's use of technological production methods. These industries are defined in a broard manner with many diverse segments so that technological labels on a specific industry can only 139 140 have limited applications. The methodology of assigning technology labels to industries is found in Davis (1982). Boertsky (1982) and Kelly (1977L 141 TABLE II-B _U.S. 1980. Two-. Three-. and Four-Digit SIC Comparative Cost Rankings Industry Value/ Comp/ Unit Rank Employ Employ Value (I) (2) (3) Meat Products 30.84 17.34 0.562 90-93 Dairy Products 50.08 18.54 0.370 19-20 Preserved Fruits 40.81 15.45 0.379 21 Grain Mill Products 80.18 21.25 0.265 5 Bakery Products 39.27 19.15 0.488 44 Sugar. Confectionery 61.03 17.96 0.294 7 Fats and Oils 66.42 20.12 0.303 10 Beverages 68.95 22.08 0.320 14 Misc. Foods Kindred 52.70 15.63 0.297 9 Tobacco Products 105.99 23.34 0.220 3-4 Weaving Mills. Cotton 21.92 13.49 0.615 121 Weaving Mills. Manmade 25.05 14.08 0.562 90—93 Weaving. Finished. Wool 25.46 14.10 0.554 81-82 Narrow Fabric Mills 20.58 12.50 0.607 116 Knitting Mills 20.42 11.67 0.571 94-95 Textile Finishing 27.50 14.41 0.524 61 Floor Covering Mills 31.10 14.38 0.463 38 Yarn and Thread Mills 20.03 12.22 0.610 118 Miscellaneous Textiles 28.52 15.26 0.535 68 Men’s and Boys' Suits 19.32 12.09 0.626 125 Men’s and Boys' Furnishings 17.78 9.44 0.531 65 Women's and Misses' Out. 16.47 9.25 0.562 90-93 Women’s.Children’s Under. 17.22 9.35 0.543 71-73 Hats. Caps. and Millinery 16.56 9.28 0.560 88-89 Children's Outerwear 15.73 8.71 0.554 81-82 Fur Goods 35.48 17.43 0.491 45 Misc. Apparel and Accs. 17.64 10.14 0.575 98 Misc. Fabricated Textile 22.71 13.04 0.574 97 _— '- Sawmills and Planning Mills Millwork. Wood Containers Wood Buildings.Mobile Homes Wood Products Misc. Household Furniture Office Furniture Public Bldg.. Related Furn. Partitions and Fixtures Furniture and Fixt. Misc. Pulpmills Papermills. Paperboard Mills Converted Paper Paperboard Cont. Boxes Building Paper.Board Mills Misc. Newspapers Periodicals Books Misc. Industrial Drugs Soaps. Paints. Misc. Petroleum Refining Paving and Roofing Mat. Petroleum. Misc. Tires and Inner Tubes Plastic Footwear Reclaimed Rubber Plastic Hose Fabricated Rubber Plastics Rubber. Rubber. Misc. p1WO°d9 Building Paper Publishing Commercial Printing Manifold Business Forms Greeting Card Publishing Blankbooks and Bookbinding Printing Trade Services Inorganic Chem. Plastic Materials.Syn. Cleaners. Allied Products Industrial Organic Chem. Agricultural Chem. Chemicals Coal Prod. 142 25.07 24.87 17.72 26.72 25.53 21.13 36.46 25.58 28.55 29.47 79.80 59.24 59.76 44.81 32.22 33.36 30.94 71.98 48.80 37.82 28.70 44.38 48.09 26.20 30.87 76.62 64.34 78.16 104.40 57.13 101.20 102.68 61.54 215.65 52.15 69.54 46.74 17.09 41.00 28.29 28.56 30.92 0.621 0.643 0.602 0.594 0.557 0.583 0.506 0.585 0.598 0.541 0.383 0.467 0.481 0.418 0.597 0.605 0.527 0.295 0.370 0.420 0.617 0.427 0.362 0.545 0.624 0.352 0.403 0.306 0.201 0.366 0.290 0.220 0.348 0.158 0.433 0.319 0.558 0.679 0.459 0.872 0.634 0.514 123 129 112 108 84 101-102 52 104 109-111 69 22 39 41 25-27 108 114-115 62-63 8 19-20 29 123 31 17 74-76 124 85-86 133 35 139 127 56-58 143 Leather Tanning Boot. Shoe Cut Stock Footwear. Expt. Rubber Leather Gloves Luggage Handbags and Purses Leather Goods Flat Glass Glass Products of Glass Cement. Hydraulic Structural Clay Pottery Concrete. Gypsum. Plaster Cut Stone Misc. Nonmetallic Miner. Blast Furnance. Steel Iron. Steel Foundries Primary Nonferrous Metals Secondary Nonferrous Nonferrous Rolling Nonferrous Foundries Misc. Primary Metal Metal Cans Cutlery. Handtools Plumbing. Heating Fabricated Struc. Screw Machine. Bolts Metal Forgings. Stamp Metal Services Ordnance Misc. Fab. Metal Engines. Turbines Farm. Garden Machinery Construction Mach. Metalworking Mach. Special Industry Mach. General Industry Mach. Office. Computing Mach. Refrigeration Misc. Machinery 29.47 19.63 20.35 10.23 25.46 16.98 20.58 48.69 39.73 29.77 69.72 28.88 27.88 38.03 22.28 44.45 45.61 32.37 75.01 48.03 47.00 29.84 41.53 67.33 36.06 34.82 33.58 33.35 35.91 27.45 34.15 36.59 52.33 45.43 47.29 39.03 35.38 39.08 47.60 39.24 29.42 16.17 10.74 10.42 7.48 12.82 9.99 10.48 29.83 22.34 17.44 29.05 16.65 16.80 18.82 13.56 20.47 32.52 23.15 31.15 21.86 24.52 19.51 20.70 28.18 19.64 17.49 19.18 19.30 23.49 15.35 22.43 19.49 27.96 23.34 24.36 22.34 21.17 21.88 22.92 20.75 18.48 0.549 0.547 0.512 0.731 0.503 0.589 0.509 0.613 0.562 0.586 0.417 0.583 0.603 0.495 0.609 0.461 0.713 0.715 0.423 0.455 0.522 0.654 0.498 0.418 0.545 0.502 0.571 0.579 0.654 0.559 0.657 0.533 0.534 0.514 0.515 0.572 0.598 0.560 0.482 0.529 0.628 79-81 77 55 138 51 106 54 119 90-93 105 24 101-102 113 47 117 36 135 136 30 34 60 130-131 48 25-27 74-76 50 94-95 100 130-131 87 132 66 67 56-58 59 96 109-111 88-89 42 64 126 144 Electric Distributing 19.45 37.84 0.514 56-58 Elect. Industrial 36.12 20.05 0.555 83 Household Appliances 38.56 17.81 0.462 37 Elec. Lighting. Wiring 35.40 17.49 0.494 46 Radio. TV Receiving 43.11 18.08 0.419 28 Communication Equip. 39.89 23.29 0.584 103 Electronic Components 33.90 18.61 0.549 78-80 Misc. Elec. Equip. 37.08 20.35 0.549 78-80 Motor Vehicles 42.73 30.27 0.708 134 Aircraft. Parts 47.58 28.45 0.598 109-111 Ship. Boat Building 26.67 21.79 0.760 138 Railroad Equipment 49.34 26.90 0.545 74-76 Motorcycles. Bicycles 31.26 16.99 0.543 71-73 Guided Missiles. Space 52.06 33.16 0.637 128 Transportation Equip. 30.94 18.72 0.605 114-115 Engineering. Scien. Inst. 40.74 20.70 0.508 53 Measuring. Controlling 35.06 20.18 0.576 99 Optical Instruments 42.29 21.17 0.501 49 Medical Instruments 36.14 17.46 0.483 43 Ophthalmic Goods 28.54 15.49 0.543 71-73 Photographic Equip. 86.96 27.32 0.314 12 Watches. Clocks 28.85 15.20 0.527 62-63 Jewelry. Silver 31.58 15.05 0.476 40 Musical Instruments 24.00 14.73 0.614 120 Toys. Sporting Goods 33.88 14.16 0.418 25-27 Pens. Office. Art Goods 35.07 15.57 0.444 33 Costume Jewelry 23.69 12.83 0.542 70 Misc. Manufactures 27.34 15.25 0.558 85-86 All Manufactures 37.48 20.37 0.543 (1) Units of average value added per employee are in thousands of dollars. (2) Units of average compensation per employee are in thousands of dollars. (3) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added. 145 TABLE III-B U.S. 1967. Two-. Three-. and Four-Digit SIC Comparative Cost Rankings Industry Value/ Comp/ Unit Rank Employ Employ Value (I) (2) (3) Meat Products 11.45 7.01 0.612 104-105 Dairy Products 14.96 6.96 0.465 28-29 Preserved Fruits 13.81 5.33 0.386 18 Grain Mill Products 25.78 7.59 0.294 5 Bakery Products 13.23 7.04 0.532 52 Sugar. Confectionery 21.10 7.67 0.363 13 Fats and Oils 15.02 5.84 0.389 19—20 Beverages 21.70 7.73 0.356 12 Misc. Foods Kindred 21.52 6.91 0.321 8 Tobacco Products 27.06 5.85 0.216 2 Weaving Mills. Cotton 8.01 5.04 0.630 115 Weaving Mills. Manmade 8.49 5.32 0.627 114 Weaving. Finished. Wool 10.25 5.67 0.553 66 Narrow Fabric Mills 8.18 5.08 0.621 107-108 Knitting Mills 7.96 4.72 0.593 85 Textile Finishing 9.63 6.21 0.645 124 Floor Covering Mills 13.75 5.77 0.420 24 Yarn and Thread Mills 7.94 4.65 0.586 83 Miscellaneous Textiles 10.98 6.15 0.560 68-69 Men's and Boys' Suits 7.71 5.25 0.681 134 Men's and Boys’ Furnishings 6.33 3.86 0.609 101-102 Women's and Misses' Out. 7.78 4.66 0.600 89 Women's. Children's Under. 7.64 4.29 0.561 70 Hats. Caps.and Millinery 6.93 4.68 0.676 132 Children’s Outerwear 6.87 4.17 0.607 97-99 Fur Goods 13.79 7.52 0.545 60-62 Misc. Apparel and Accs. 7.21 4.42 0.612 104-105 Misc. Fabricated Textile 8.43 5.01 0.594 86 Logging Camps 9.85 5.27 0.535 56 Sawmills and Planning Mills 8.28 5.27 0.637 119-120 Millwork. Plywood. Struc. 9.78 6.43 0.658 127 Wood Containers 7.62 4.74 0.622 109 Misc. Wood Products 9.08 5.33 84 0.587 146 Household Furniture 8.90 5.37 0.603 90 Office Furniture 13.58 7.16 0.528 50-51 Public Bldg.. Related Furn. 10.34 6.52 0.631 116-118 Partitions and Fixtures 12.23 7.42 0.607 97-99 Misc. Furniture and Fixt. 10.24 6.20 0.605 91-94 Pulpmills 22.10 9.24 0.418 23 Papermills. Building Paper 16.83 8.98 0.534 54-55 Paperboard Mills 22.52 8.93 0.396 21 Misc. Converted Paper 15.18 7.06 0.465 28-29 Paperboard Cont. Boxes 11.62 7.04 0.606 95-96 Building Paper. Board Mill 15.70 7.95 0.506 40 Newspapers 12.46 7.25 0.582 78-79 Periodicals 23.62 8.79 0.372 14 Books 20.39 7.84 0.385 17 Misc. Publishing 13.42 6.91 0.515 47-48 Commercial Printing 11.93 7.71 0.647 125 Manifold Business Forms 16.00 7.61 0.476 30 Greeting Card Publishing 62.05 28.18 0.454 26 Blankbooks and Bookbinding 9.45 6.05 0.640 121-122 Printing Trade Services 12.88 9.30 0.722 138 Industrial Inorganic Chem 31.16 9.53 0.306 6 Plastic Materials. Syn. 27.57 10.72 0.389 19-20 Drugs 34.55 8.99 0.260 4 Soaps. Cleaners. Toilet 40.56 7.92 0.195 1 Paints. Allied Products 19.95 8.29 0.416 22 Industrial Organic Chem. 17.08 6.39 0.374 15 Agricultural Chem. 22.01 6.85 0.311 7 Misc. Chemicals 17.97 7.93 0.441 25 Petroleum Refining 44.47 10.4 0.234 3 Paving and Roofing Mat. 17.20 7.88 0.458 27 Misc. Petroleum. Coal Prod. 26.80 8.64 0.323 9 Tires and Inner Tubes 19.67 9.75 0.496 38 Rubber. Plastic Footwear 8.42 5.61 0.667 129-131 Reclaimed Rubber 13.76 8.41 0.611 103 Fabricated Rubber 12.29 7.46 0.607 97-99 Misc. Plastics 11.80 6.35 0.538 57 Leather Tanning 10.40 6.78 0.652 126 Industrial Leather Belting 11.67 6.44 0.552 65 Boot. Shoe Cut Stock 7.97 4.75 0.596 88 Footwear. Expt. Rubber 7.67 4.64 0.605 91-94 Leather Gloves 5.76 3.92 0.680 133 Luggage 8.69 4.93 0.568 72-73 Handbags and Purses 7.57 4.87 0.643 123 Leather Goods 7.46 4.70 0.631 116-118 Flat Glass Glass Products of Glass Cement. Hydraulic Structural Clay Pottery Concrete. Gypsum. Plaster Cut Stone Misc. Nonmetallic Miner. Blast Furnance. Steel Iron. Steel Foundries Primary Nonferrous Metals Secondary Nonferrous Nonferrous Rolling Nonferrous Foundries Misc. Primary Metal Metal Cans Cutlery. Handtools Plumbing. Heating Fabricated Struc. Screw Machine. Bolts Metal Forgings. Stamp Metal Services Misc. Wire Products Misc. Fab. Metal Engines. Turbines Farm. Garden Machinery Construction Mach. Metalworking Mach. Special Industry Mach. General Industry Mach. Office. Computing Mach. Refrigeration Misc. Machinery Electric Distributing Elect. Industrial Household Appliances Elec. Lighting. Wiring Radio. TV Receiving Communication Equip. Electronic Components Misc. Elec. Equip. 147 9.54 7.03 6.95 8.79 6.35 6.48 7.18 5.96 7.69 9.56 8.12 8.71 8.05 8.43 7.63 9.13 9.15 7.55 7.34 7.74 8.13 8.55 6.47 6.72 7.75 9.32 8.00 8.49 9.38 8.45 8.60 8.49 7.61 7.81 7.82 7.70 7.34 6.79 6.27 9.30 6.74 7.60 0.539 0.511 0.515 0.353 0.626 0.661 0.490 0.667 0.528 0.580 0.718 0.337 0.510 0.494 0.640 0.613 0.483 0.508 0.549 0.609 0.582 0.637 0.608 0.605 0.564 0.583 0.534 0.560 0.621 0.606 0.585 0.485 0.500 0.625 0.547 0.570 0.489 0.482 0.514 0.699 0.623 0.545 58 43 47-48 11 113 128 36 129-131 50-51 77 137 10 42 37 121-122 106 32 41 64 101-102 78-79 119-120 100 91-94 71 80-81 54-55 68-69 107-108 95-96 82 33 39 112 63 74 34-35 31 46 135 110-111 60-62 148 18.48 Motor Vehicles 9.47 0.512 44 Aircraft. Parts 14.12 10.10 0.715 136 Ship. Boat Building 10.07 8.12 0.806 139 Railroad Equipment 13.92 8.67 0.623 110-111 Motorcycles. Bicycles 11.35 6.51 0.573 75 Misc. Transport Equip. 10.06 6.09 0.605 91-94 Engineering. Scien. Inst. 13.39 7.80 0.583 80-81 Measuring. Controlling 13.34 7.73 0.579 76 Optical Instruments 13.64 8.61 0.631 116-117 Medical Instruments 14.33 7.01 0.489 34-35 Ophthalmic Goods 11.19 6.20 0.554 67 Photographic Equip. 26.14 9.80 0.375 16 Watches. Clocks 11.16 6.64 0.595 87 Jewelry. Silver 12.25 6.68 0.545 60-62 Musical Instruments 9.55 6.37 0.667 129-131 Toys. Sporting Goods 10.40 5.34 0.513 45 Pens. Office. Art Goods 11.88 6.33 0.533 53 Costume Jewelry 10.23 5.39 0.526 49 Misc. Manufactures 10.95 6.23 0.568 72-73 (1) Units of average value added per employee are in thousands of dollars. (2) Units of average compensation per employee are in thousands of dollars. (3) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added. 149 TABLE IV-B U.S. 1980 ISIC Comparative Cost Rankings UNIT RANK INDUSTRY VALUE/ COMP/ EMPLOY EMPLOY LABOR COSTS (I) (2) (3) Food Products 47.14 17.76 0.377 5 Beverages 62.89 22.15 0.352 4 Tobacco 105.99 23.33 0.220 2 Textiles 23.45 12.97 0.553 19 Wearing Apparel 17.23 9.57 0.555 20 Leather and Products 21.82 12.01 0.550 18 Footwear 20.30 10.45 0.515 15 Wood Products 25.83 15.21 0.589 24 Furniture. Fixtures 24.61 13.99 0.569 22 Paper and Products 46.05 21.99 0.478 9 Printing. Publishing 35.14 17.36 0.494 11 Industrial Chemicals 58.27 26.88 0.461 8 Other Chemical Products 79.61 22.19 0.279 3 Petroleum Refineries 215.65 34.00 0.158 I Petroleum. Coal Products 57.76 22.47 0.389 6 Rubber Products 34.47 21.51 0.624 26 Plastic Products n.e.c. 30.92 15.88 0.514 14 Pottery. China. etc. 27.88 16.80 0.603 25 Glass and Products 38.17 21.89 0.573 23 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 40.89 19.70 0.482 10 Iron and Steel 41.51 29.62 0.714 28 Nonferrous Metals 47.00 24.01 0.511 13 Metal Products 35.82 20.25 0.565 21 Machinery n.e.c. 41.25 22.32 0.541 17 Electrical Machinery 37.26 20.11 0.540 16 Transport Equipment 43.22 28.37 0.656 27 Professional Goods 45.28 20.63 0.456 7 Other Industries 29.62 14.67 0.495 12 All Manufactures 20.37 0.543 (1) Units of average (2) Units 37.48 value added per thousands of dollars. of average compensation per thousands of dollars. (3) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added. employee are employee are in in Japanese 1980 Comparative Cost Rankings INDUSTRY 150 TABLE V-B RANK (1) Units of average value added per employee are million yen. (2) Units of average wage per employee are in million yen. (3) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added. VALUE/ WAGES/ UNIT EMPLOY EMPLOY LABOR COSTS (1) (2) (3) Food Products 5.76 1.94 0.336 10 Beverages 11.30 2.53 0.224 4 Tobacco 0 4.63 0 28 Textiles 4.16 1.83 0.439 21 Wearing Apparel 2.33 1.23 0.526 27 Leather and Products 4.19 1.91 0.456 24 Footwear 4.38 2.03 0.463 25 Wood Products 4.33 1.93 0.444 22 Furniture. Fixtures 4.89 2.05 0.418 20 Paper and Products 7.42 2.67 0.359 11 Printing. Publishing 7.70 3.11 0.403 17 Industrial Chemicals 14.72 3.75 0.254 5 Other Chemical Products 17.26 3.33 0.193 2 Petroleum Refineries 51.76 4.34 0.084 1 Petroleum. Coal Products 15.67 3.20 0.204 3 Rubber Products 7.09 2.77 0.391 15 Plastic Products n.e.c. 6.23 2.30 0.370 12 Pottery. China. etc. 4.27 1.99 0.466 26 Glass and Products 10.45 3.11 0.298 8 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 7.66 2.45 0.319 9 -Iron and Steel 13.88 3.76 0.271 6 Nonferrous Metals 11.58 3.15 0.272 7 Metal Products 6.12 2.49 0.407 18 Machinery n.e.c. 7.67 3.06 0.399 16 Electrical Machinery 6.58 2.45 0.372 13 Transport Equipment 8.27 3.14 0.379 14 Professional Goods 5.36 2.38 0.445 23 Other Industries 5.16 2.13 0.414 19 All Manufactures 7.20 2.55 0.355 151 TABLE VI-B German 1980 Comparative Cost Rankings INDUSTRY VALUE/ COMP/ UNIT RANK EMPLOY EMPLOY LABOR COSTS (1) (2) (3) Food Products 97.6 28.3 0.290 3 Beverages 107.8 34.2 0.317 4 Tobacco 551.3 33.0 0.060 I Textiles 39.8 25.5 0.641 23 Wearing Apparel 40.1 20.0 0.498 10 Leather. Footwear. etc. 42.7 22.8 0.534 13 Wood. Furniture. etc. 63.5 29.9 0.471 8 Paper and Products 54.1 31.4 0.580 18 Printing. Publishing 60.2 35.2 0.585 19 Industrial Chemicals 75.5 40.6 0.538 14 Petroleum Refineries 825.9 50.0 0.061 2 Rubber Products 55.2 32.7 0.592 20 Plastic Products n.e.c. 53.3 29.3 0.549 15 Pottery. China. etc. 56.7 25.0 0.441 6 Glass and Products 59.2 31.4 0.531 12 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 84.7 34.3 0.405 5 Iron and Steel 67.3 34.9 0.519 11 Nonferrous Metals 42.5 35.0 0.824 24 Metal Products 52.2 32.7 0.626 22 Machinery n.e.c. 57.8 36.1 0.625 21 Electrical Machinery 60.1 33.7 0.560 16 Transport Equipment 66.3 38.3 0.578 17 Professional Goods 67.3 31.0 0.461 7 Other Industries 53.3 25.7 0.481 9 All Manufactures 67.8 33.6 0.495 (1) thousand marks. (2) thousand marks. (3) Units of average value added per employee are in Units of average compensation per employee are in Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added 152 TABLE VII-B U.K. 1980 Comparative Cost Rankings INDUSTRY VALUE/ COMP/ UNIT RANK EMPLOY EMPLOY LABOR COSTS (I) (2) (3) Food Products 11.46 5.37 0.469 8 Beverages 21.18 6.42 0.303 2 Tobacco 21.67 6.94 0.320 3 Textiles 6.68 4.70 0.704 25 Wearing Apparel 5.35 3.90 0.729 26 Leather and Products 7.50 4.78 0.637 21 Footwear 7.12 4.80 0.674 24 Wood Products 9.62 5.59 0.581 13 Furniture. Fixtures 9.32 5.97 0.641 22 Paper and Products 10.50 6.24 0.594 18 Printing. Publishing 13.40 6.93 0.517 9 Industrial Chemicals 17.12 7.89 0.461 7 Other Chemical Products 17.55 6.15 0.350 4 Petroleum Refineries 114.12 9.35 0.082 I Petroleum. Coal Products 19.38 7.00 0.361 5 Rubber Products . 10.52 6.21 0.590 16 Plastic Products n.e.c. 10.46 5.76 0.551 11 Pottery. China. etc. 7.64 5.05 0.661 23 Glass and Products 11.48 6.80 0.592 17 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 16.44 6.45 0.392 6 Iron and Steel 7.75 6.53 0.843 28 Nonferrous Metals 11.33 6.62 0.584 14 Metal Products 9.75 6.00 0.615 20 Machinery n.e.c. 11.09 6.29 0.567 12 Electrical Machinery 9.83 5.80 0.590 15 Transport Equipment 9.05 6.61 0.730 27 Professional Goods 9.50 5.65 0.595 19 Other Industries 9.17 4.93 0.538 10 All Manufactures 10.89 0.553 (1) Units of average thousand pounds. (2) Units of average thousand pounds. (3) Unit labor costs compensation/value-added. are defined as value added per employee are in compensation per employee are in 153 TABLE VIII-B Italian 1980 Comparative Cost Rankings VALUE/ COMP/ UNIT RANK INDUSTRY EMPLOY EMPLOY LABOR (I) (2) (3) Food Products 30.96 13.83 0.447 3 Beverages 43.39 15.64 0.360 2 Tobacco 13.15 9.85 0.749 23 Textiles 19.43 10.86 0.559 15 Wearing Apparel 15.92 9.27 0.582 17 Leather and Products 21.96 10.57 0.481 6 Footwear 15.42 9.04 0.586 18 Wood Products 22.14 10.69 0.483 7 Furniture. Fixtures 22.11 10.89 0.493 8 Paper and Products 28.90 14.43 0.499 10 Printing. Publishing 29.70 16.94 0.570 16 Industrial Chemicals 34.20 16.25 0.475 5 Petroleum Refineries 601.11 19.42 0.032 1 Rubber Products 24.52 15.14 0.618 21 Plastic Products n.e.c. 16.96 12.82 0.756 24 Pottery. China. etc. 26.86 12.65 0.471 4 Iron and Steel 29.81 14.85 0.498 9 Nonferrous Metals 22.52 13.86 0.615 20 Metal Products 23.53 12.77 0.543 12-13 Machinery n.e.c. 26.19 14.21 0.543 12-13 Electrical Machinery 21.83 13.41 0.614 19 Transport Equipment 21.06 13.44 0.638 22 Professional Goods 27.19 14.72 0.541 11 Other Industries 20.16 11.03 0.547 14 All Manufactures 24.65 13.25 0.537 (1) Units of average hundred thousand (2) Units of average hundred thousand (3) Unit labor costs value added per employee are in lira. compensation per employee are in lira. are defined as compensation/value-added. 154 TABLE IX-B U.S. 1967 Comparative Cost Rankings INDUSTRY VALUE/ COMP/ UNIT RANK EMPLOY EMPLOY LABOR COSTS (I) (2) (3) Food Products 15.58 5.99 0.384 7 Beverages 19.95 6.87 0.344 4 Tobacco 27.07 5.07 0.187 1 Textiles 8.79 4.71 0.536 21 Wearing Apparel 7.25 4.05 0.558 25 Leather and Products 8.78 5.00 0.570 26 Footwear 7.69 4.22 0.549 23 Wood Products 8.88 5.10 0.574 27 Furniture. Fixtures 9.27 5.15 0.555 24 Paper and Products 15.27 6.95 0.455 11 Printing. Publishing 13.93 6.94 0.498 15 Industrial Chemicals 26.78 7.84 0.293 3 Other Chemical Products 22.42 8.19 0.365 5 Petroleum Refineries 44.30 8.97 0.203 2 Petroleum. Coal Products 19.43 7.14 0.368 6 Rubber Products 14.45 6.98 0.483 13 Plastic Products n.e.c. 11.79 5.71 0.485 14 Pottery. China. etc. 9.77 5.81 0.595 28 Glass and Products 14.32 6.60 0.461 12 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 14.55 6.52 0.448 9 Iron and Steel 15.04 7.85 0.522 19 Nonferrous Metals 16.62 7.37 0.444 8 Metal Products 13.38 6.90 0.516 18 Machinery n.e.c. 14.80 7.57 0.511 17 Electrical Machinery 13.22 6.96_ 0.526 20 Transport Equipment 15.35 8.26 0.538 22 Professional Goods 15.83 7.15 0.452 10 Other Industries 10.76 5.39 0.501 16 All Manufactures g14.18 6.68 0.471 Units of thousands (1) average value added per employee are in of dollars. (2) Units of average compensation per employee are in thousands of dollars. (3) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/value-added. 155 TABLE X-B Japanese 1967 Comparative Cost Rankings WAGES/ UNIT INDUSTRY VALUE/ RANK EMPLOY EMPLOY LABOR COSTS (I) (2) (3) Food Products 1.29 0.39 0.304 10 Beverages 2.21 0.44 0.198 4 Tobacco 0 0.91 0 28 Textiles 0.99 0.37 0.371 18 Wearing Apparel 0.71 0.30 0.418 25 Leather and Products 1.24 0.47 0.383 21 Footwear 1.17 0.46 0.393 23 Wood Products 0.99 0.39 0.391 22 Furniture. Fixtures 0.97 0.42 0.427 26 Paper and Products 1.62 0.52 0.320 13 Printing. Publishing 1.73 0.65 0.375 19 Industrial Chemicals 3.77 0.71 0.187 2 Other Chemical Products 3.18 0.60 0.188 3 Petroleum Refineries 7.86 0.86 0.109 1 Petroleum. Coal Products 2.00 0.53 0.267 6 Rubber Products 1.50 0.48 0.322 14 Plastic Products n.e.c. 1.33 0.45 0.338 15 Pottery. China. etc. 0.88 0.40 0.453 27 Glass and Products 2.28 0.58 0.254 5 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 1.57 0.47 0.301 9 Iron and Steel 2.55 0.76 0.299 8 Nonferrous Metals 2.40 0.67 0.282 7 Metal Products 1.36 0.52 0.379 20 Machinery n.e.c. 1.63 0.59 0.359 17 Electrical Machinery 1.58 0.49 0.312 11 Transport Equipment 1.96 0.62 0.316 12 Professional Goods 1.26 0.52 0.417 24 Other Industries 1.17 0.42 0.355 16 All Manufactures 1.59 0.319 0.51 (1) million yen. (2) million yen. (3) Units of average value added per employee are in Units of average wage per employee are in Unit labor costs are defined as wages/value-added. 156 TABLE XI-B German 1967 Comparative Cost Rankings INDUSTRY OUTPUT/ WAGES/ UNIT EMPLOY EMPLOY LABOR COSTS (1) (2) (3) Food Products 113.6 10.8 0.095 Beverages 80.9 12.1 0.149 Tobacco 264.7 9.7 0.037 Textiles 39.8 9.2 0.232 Wearing Apparel 30.7 7.4 0.240 Leather and Footwear 34.0 8.1 0.239 Wood Products.Furniture 42.8 10.4 0.242 Paper and Products 49.7 11.0 0.222 Printing. Publishing 32.5 12.0 0.370 Industrial Chemicals 71.2 14.3 0.201 Petroleum Refineries.Coal 430.3 16.7 0.039 Rubber Products 41.3 13.0 0.316 Plastic Products n.e.c. 41.6 11.8 0.283 Pottery. China. etc. 25.3 9.9 0.390 Glass and Products 37.5 11.5 0.306 Nonmetal Products n.e.c. 50.0 12.2 0.244 Iron and Steel 50.6 12.4 0.246 Nonferrous Metals 67.3 12.4 0.184 Metal Products 39.8 11.5 0.288 Machinery n.e.c. 38.3 12.3 0.321 Electrical Machinery 36.0 11.5 0.319 Transport Equipment 48.9 13.6 0.277 Professional Goods 27.2 10.3 0.381 Other Industries 31.7 8.9 0.280 All Manufactures 49.7 11.6 0.233 (1) Value added data were not available for Germany in 1967. Instead. gross output was substituted in an attempt to obtain a ranking system. Units of average gross output per employee are in thousand marks. (2) Units of average wage per employee are in thousand marks. (3) Unit labor costs are defined as compensation/gross-output. 157 Table XII-B Comparative Rankings of U.S.. and Italian Manufacturing Industries in 1980 Food Products Beverages Tobacco Textiles Wearing Apparel Leather and Products Footwear Wood Products Furniture. Fixtures Paper and Products Printing. Publishing Industrial Chemicals Other Chemical Products Petroleum Refineries Petroleum. Coal Product Rubber Products Plastic Products n.e.c. Pottery. China. etc. Glass and Products Nonmetal Products Iron and Steel Nonferrous Metals Metal Products Machinery n.e.c. Electrical Machinery Transport Equipment Professional Goods Other Industries Japanese. German. U.K.. JAPAN GERMANY U.K. ITALY 3 8 3 4 2 2 I 3 23 23 25 15 10 26 17 13 21 6 - 24 18 8 13 7 - 22 B 18 18 10 19 9 16 14 7 5 - 4 _ 2 1 1 _ 5 _ 20 16 21 15 11 24 6 23 4 12 17 - 5 6 - II 28 9 24 14 20 22 20 12-13 21 12 12-13 16 15 19 17 27 22 7 19 11 9 10 14 APPENDIX C An Extension and Empirical Test of Comparative Advantage This section extends and tests empirically Deardorff“s (1980) formulation of comparative advantage. Heideveloped a general model of comparative advantage whose conclusion is that there must exist a negative correlation between a country"s autarky prices and its pattern of net exports. This is demonstrated in his theorem below. if Pa’Tni o, (l) where Pa is a vector of autarky prices and T is net exports for n industries. then coritxl.x2) _<_ 0 as xliixz $0. The assumptions of the model are (I) the production possibilities set. given its technolOQY. is closed. convex, and bounded from above: (2) a country”s preferences can be represented by a family of community indifference curves exhibiting the property of local nonsatiation: (3) producers and consumers behave competitively to maximize the value of net output and utility of consumption: and (A) no trade subsidies exist. The significance of this model lies in the assumptions that were not made. namely that: (1) utility and production functions are not assumed to be differentiable: (2) utility 158 159 functions need not be homothetic: and (3) neither functions are assumed to be identical across countries. Thus. countries can differ in tastes. technologies. and factor endowments. Deardorff extends the model by examining the ratio of autarky to world prices. Pi = Pal/PWJ j=1.u.n: (2) where P8 and Pw are autarky and world prices respectively and j is the industries. Next consider a country’s net exports valued at world prices. ej = iji'Tnj. (3) Then assuming balanced trade. Zej = pwj'Tnj = e. (A) By examining the product f)*e. we obtain f'e = illDEIJ/ia‘"J - ”"3”3n = zpaji‘rnj = Pa'Tn. Thus. from the theorem in equation 1. cor(f’.e) g 0. (5) This is Deardorff"s first corrollary. We can now extend the model by examining a competitive market where PhJ = MCJ. PhJ is the domestic price of good j. If we define a production function employing two factors. capital-K. and labor-L. 05 = f(KJ.LJ). (6) Then by allowing the production function to be differentiable. MC.j s wJ/MP‘J = rJ/MPkJ. (7) Multiplying through to obtain factor prices and factor 160 costs. MPIJ.MCj = NJ and MPIJ.LJ.MCj = WJTLJ‘ (8) Npkj-ch = r3 and Mij'Kj'MCJ = rj*KJ. . (9) By adding the two equations to derive total factor costs. MCj*(MP.j*Lj + Mij*Kj) = wj*Lj + rj*Kj. (IO) and MCj = (wj*Lj + rJ*KJ)/(MP‘1*LJ + MPkJ*KJ). (ll) Multiplying through by QJ/QJ. M.. = i’ .* P * ’ . CJ _(wJ LJ + rJ Kfi/Q.) [Qj/(MP.J*LJ + 14ka an. (12) This simplifies into equation 13. where MC = ZMCJ. MC = AC/(function coefficient) = Ph. (13) and Ph is the vector of home prices. If the function coefficient (fc) is greater than one, then increasing returns to scale hold. Similarly if fc =1. constant returns to scale hold. and if fc < I. then decreasing returns. If. as an approximation. we assume that Ph = Pa. then substituting equation 13 into equation 5 yields. cert(Ach/Ac")*(fc"’/fc").e) g 0. (14) This formulation provides a method of testing trade theories of scale economies within a comparative cost framework. Due to the unavailability of world functional coefficient data. the empirical testing of this hypothesis required the assumption that fcw be equal to fch. This assumption is not unreasonable since the H-0 hypothesis assumes both identical production functions across countries and constant returns to scale. while the Ricardian model 161 assumes the latter. Thus. compared to the standard trade theories. the assumption that fcw = fch is more flexible. Although economies of scale must be equal in the same industry worldwide. they do not have to be equal to one and can vary among industries. The average costs of an industry is approximated by relative unit labor costs. These are defined as an industry"s unit labor costs relative to average in all other industries. In turn. unit labor costs consist of labor productivity per employee and labor compensation per employee. Since this dissertation examines five countries. the United States. Japan. Germany. the United Kingdom. and Italy. a weighted average of these will approximate world costs. The weights are value added as a percentage of world value added, thus reflecting the relativelimportance of a country"s unit labor cost in an industry. The weights are as follows: (vji/ §\Vji)/ é‘ivji/ é‘vi). (15) where VJ. is the value added of industry j in country i for m countries and n industries. The sign of equation 14 can be derived from the sign of the covariance between the vectors where. cor(Uh/Uw.e) = cov(Uh/U",e) (16) [ ..Z'EBFZBQTI"JQ...1 i» - . 5 Since the denominator is nonnegative. the correlation and covariance must have the same sign. Although only the 162 ,covariance matrix is needed for testing the Deardorff model. both will be presented in Table C1 with net exports specified both as exports minus imports and as a ratio. The results of the covariance matrix yielded the expected sign in eight of the ten cases. For the two cases where the wrong sign occured. the correlation matrix indicated a weaker magitude compared with the alternate specification of net exports. Considering the multitude of factors determining trade flows. these results strongly support the extension of the Deardorff model. The conclusion is that comparative advantage. based on relative unit labor costs. is an important determinate of net exports. This extension of Deardorff’s model uses less restrictive assumptions than the standard trade models. provides a comparative coSt framework for testing scale economies. and fits the data well. Thus. it should be considered in further studies of the determinants of international trade flows. 163 Table C1 Covariance and Correlation Matrices Between Net Exports and Relative Unit Labor Costs for I980. Covariance Matrix Country X-M X/M Germany 276978.8 -0.04185 Italy -31.8994 -0.00773 U.S. -162.164 0.02656 Japan -315279 -0.22299 U.K. -66.891 -0.01674 Correlation Matrix Country X-M X/M Germany 0.16276 —0.21068 Italy -0.14355 -0.12525 U.S. —0.27454 0.15516 Japan -0.23181 -0.27515 U.K -0.26251 —0.18855 BIBLIOGRAPHY Allen. William. International Trade Theory: Hume tg Ohlin. New York: Random House. 1965. Anderson. Richard. and Kreinen. Mordechai. "Labor Cost and U.S. Comparative Advantage in Steel and Motor Vechicles". The World Economy. June 1981. Angell. James. The Theory gfi International Prices. Boston: Harvard University Press. 1926. "Annual Report on American Industry." Forbes. January 2. 1984. pp. 99-243. Balassa. Bela. "An Empirical Demonstration of Classical Comparative Cost Theory". The Review 9f Economics and Statistics. August 1963. pp. 231-38. . 'Revealed' Comparative Advantage Revisted: An Analysis of Relative Export Shares of the Industrial Countries. 1953-1971”.The figgchester School. 1977. pp.327-44. . ”Trade Liberalization and 'Revealed' Comparative Advantage" The flgnchester School. May 1965. pp. 99-123. Bhagwati. Jadish. ”Pure Theory of International Trade: A Survey". In: Jadish Bhagwati (ed.). Trade. Tariffs. gag growthl Essays lg Interngtiongl Economics. London: Weidenfeld 5 Nicolson. 1969. pp. 3-94. Boretsky. M.. ”The Threat to U.S. High Technology Industries:Economic and National Security Implications." Draft. International Trade Administration. U.S. Department of Commerce. March 1982. Caves. Richard. and Ronald Jones. World Trade and Payments: Ag Introduction. third ed.. Boston: Little. Brown and Company. 1981. Chipman. John. ”A Survey of the Theory of International Trade: Part 1. The Classical Theory". Econometrica. 33. July 1965. pp. 477-519. 164 I65 Daly. J. ”Uses of International Price and Output Data". In: D.J. Daly (ed.). International Comparisons gfi Prices and Output. Studies in Income and Wealth. Vol. 27. New York: Columbia University Press for National Bureau of Economic Research. 1972. Davis. L.A.. "Technology Intensity of U.S. Output abd Trade." Office of Trade abd Investment Analysis. U.S. Department of Commerce. February 1982. Deardorff. Alan. "The General Validity of the Law of Comparative Advantage”. Journal gfi Political Economy. October 1980. pp. 941—57. Denison. Edward. Why Growth Rgtes Differ-Postwar Experience 1g Nine Western Countries. Washington. D.C.: Brookings Institution. 1967. Haberler. Gottfried. The Theory 9f Interngtiongl Tradez with its Applicgtions 59 Commercial Policy. (translated From the German by Alfred Stonier and Frederic Benham). New York: The Macmillan Co.. 1936. Graham. Frank. "The Theory of International Values Re- examined". Quarterly Journal 9f Egonomics. November 1923. p. 54-86. Johnson. J. Econometric Methogg. second ed.. New York: McGraw-Hill. 1972. Jones. Ronald. "’Two-ness’ in Trade Theory: Costs and Benefits". International Trade: Essays 1g Theory. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co.. 1979. Judge. George. et al.The Theory and Practice gfi Econometrigg. New York: John Wiley and Sons. 1980. Kelly. R.K.. "The Impact of Technological Innovation on International Trade Patterns." Office of International Economic Research. U.S. Department of Commerce. December 1977. Kmenta. Jan. Elements gf Egonometrics. New York: Macmillion. 1971. Koopmans. Tjalling. "Maximization and Substitution in Linear Models of Production". Igput-Ogtput Relations (edited by the Netherlands Institute). Leiden: H.E. Stenfert Kroese N.V.. 1953. pp.99-109. Kravis. Irving. "'Availability' and Other Influences of the Commodity Composition of Trade". Journal 9f Political Economy. April 1956. pp. 143-55. 166 . ”Wages and Foreign Trade". The Review gf Economics and Statistics. February 1956. pp. 14-30. Kreinin. Mordechai. International Economics: A Policy Aggroach. fourth ed.. New York: Harcourt. Brace. Jovanovich. Inc.. 1983. "Labor Costs and Comparative Advantage in Motor Vechicles and Steel: Further Analysis and Extensions". unpublished paper. Michigan State University. 1983. pp. 1-20. "The Theory of Comparative Cost-Further Empirical Evidence". Economia Internagjonale. November 1969. pp. 662-73. . ”United States' Comparative Advantage in Motor Vechicles and Steel". included as Chapter 6 in Brazer and Laren (eds.) Michigan's Fiscal ggg Economic Structure. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 1982. pp. 150-176. . "Wage Competiveness in the U.S. Auto and Steel Industries". Contemporary Poligy Issues. January 1984. pp. 39-50. Lary. Hal. Imgorts gfi Manufactures from Less Developed Countries. New York: NBER. 1968. Lebergott. Stanley. "Wages and Structures". The Review gfi Economics and Statistics. November 1947. PP. 274—85. MacDougall. Donald. "British and American Exports: A Study Suggested By the Theory of Comparative Costs. Part I". The Economic gournal. December 1951. pp. 697-724. . Monica Dowley. Pauline Fox. and Senta Pugh. "British and American Productivity Prices. and Exports: An Addendum”. Oxford Economic Pagers. October 1962. pp. 297—304. Marks. Stephen. "Comment on Kreinin". Contemporary Policy Issues. January 1984. pp. 51-53. Mill. John Stuart. Principles 9f Political Economy. edited by W.J. Ashley. London: Longman’s Green. and Co.. 1909. Minhas. Bagiche. "The Homohypallagic Production Function. Factor Intensity Reversals. and the Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem". Journal 9f Political Economy. April 1962. Pp. 138-56. 167 Niroomand. Farhang. "Determinants of the Structure of U.S. Foreign Trade in Manufacturingi963-I980." Diss. Michigan State University. 1983. Parry. Thomas. ”Trade and Non-trade Performance in U.S. Manufacturing Industry-Revealed Comparative Advantage". The Manchester School. 1975. pp. 158-72. Ricardo. David. Qg the Principles gf Political Economy. and Taxation. in The Works ggg Correspondence 9f David Ricardo. Vol. 1. ed. by Piero Sraffa. Cambridge. U.K.: Cambridge University Press. 1951. Samuelson. Paul. "Abstract of 8 Theorem Concerning Substitutability in Open Leontief Models". Activity Analysis 9f Prodgction ggg Allocgtion (edited by Koopmans). New York: John Wiley. 1951. pp. 142-146. Schmidt. Peter. Econometrics. New York: Marcel Dekker. inc.. 1976. Stern. Robert. “British and American Productivity and Comparative Costs in International Trade". Oxford Economic Pagers. October 1962. PP. 275-296. - — . "Testing Trade Theories". In: Peter Kenen (ed.). Interngtiongl Trade and Fingnce: Frontiers for Research. New York: Cambridge University Press. 1975. pp. 3-49. Stryker. J. Dirck. "The Sources of Change in Export Performance: The United States and Canada". in Kenen and Lawrence. eds.. Igg. Ogen Economy: Essays gg International Trade and Finance. New York: Columbia University Press. 1968. pp. 150-74. Takayama. Akira. International Trade: gg Aggroach g9 the Theory. New York: Holt. Rinehart. and Winston. 1972. Taussig. Frank. International Trade. New York: The Macmillan Co.. 1927. -------------- . Princigles gfi Economics. Vol. I. second ed.. New York: The Macmillian Co.. 1919. Torrens. Robert. Ag Essay gg the Exterggl Corn Trade. reprint. Clifton. N.J.: Augustus Kelly. 1972. Viner. Jacob. Studies 1g the Theory gf International Igggg. New York: Harper 8 Row. 1937. "liliiillWilli?)