t: THESlS‘ ' LIE RaBY - This is to certify that the dissertation entitled THE RWANDAN COLONIAL ECONOMY l9l6 - 19‘” presented by Learthen Dorsey has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degreein History W 22/,2, flajor professor Date August ll, l983 MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE «~31 (JUL 0 9 2007 {I t‘i‘ 2/05 p:lClRC/DaleDue.indd-p.1 ‘fim / 7/ — a—é/agy THE RWANDAN COLONIAL ECONOMY, 1916 - 1941 BY Learthen Dorsey A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of History 1983 Copyright by LEARTHEN DORSEY 1983 ABSTRACT THE RWANDAN COLONIAL ECONOMY, 1916 - 1941 BY Learthen Dorsey This study examines the development of the colonial state and the changes it introduced into the social and economic life of the Rwandan peasantry. It also des- cribes the introduction<1fthe compulsory coffee cultivation and its impact on both the ruling Batutsi oligarchy and the Bahutu masses. A cash economy combined with the spread of Christianity and western education transformed the ideas and manners of the traditional society. How did ordinary Rwandans or the peasantry cope with these changes? What was the range of their options? These questions are addressed here. A combination of research methods and techniques were employed. Primary and secondary source materials were consulted in the United States, Belgium and Rwanda. Also, coffee growers in Butare and other informants were ques— tioned following an interview guide. As a result, this study finds that the decision-making power and alternative choices of Rwandans were severely limited by the demands of the colonial state and the civilian administration or the Batutsi oligarchy. State intervention in the economy, designed to create capital surplus and facilitate the Learthen Dorsey develOpment of civil administration and the country's infrastructure, was partially responsible for this. However, the depression of the 19305 was also responsible for changing the status of Rwandans. The economic crisis severely weakened the emerging capitalist sector, and threatened both colonial solvency and the colony's develop- ment. To compensate for lost revenues, colonial officials increased receipts, taxes and charges on the producers, thereby severely weakening the small but growing African capitalist sector. At the same time, the state, in order to ensure the growth of capitalism, was compelled to introduce cash crop production, to reorganize the traditional structure and standardize the lines of communication from the admini— stration through chiefs and subchiefs, to the rural population. While these measures fostered agricultural development, they inadvertently tightened the stranglehold of the Batutsi notables over Bahutu, and redirected indivi- dual African initiative in the domestic economy for the benefit of the state, and introduced into the country a strict system of economic planning which guaranteed the maximum productivity from the African masses. To my mother and father and my brothers, Jeff, Harrison and George iii AC KNOW LE DGEMENTS I want to thank the members of my committee for their guidance, support and encouragement. I am deeply indebted to Harry Reed for his friendship and guidance over the many years. And I wish to thank David Robinson for those very long and much appreciated critiques of each of the chapters of the manuscript. Leslie B. Rout Jr. and the late David Bailey are responsible for much of what I know about Latin American history, and John Hinnant gave me the tools for which I needed to do field work. As for Harold Marcus, my chairman, I must extend a very special thanks. His careful reading and scrutiny of the manuscript made the difference. No acknowledgement would be complete without an expression of profound gratitude for the Ford Foundation and the National Defense Foreign Language Fellowship. This manuscript could not have been completed without their financial assistance. Nor could I have conducted my research without the full support and cooperation of my friends and informants in Rwanda. Louis and Mathias were good friends and translators, and the National University and the Institute for Scientific Research at Butare provided essential services. iv TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION.. ...... . ....... .. ............. . .............. .1 Chapter I THE AFRICAN BACKGROUND AND THE GERMAN COLONIAL STATEOCOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOC0.0.0....0.0.0.14 II THE BELGIAN COLONIAL STATE AND INDIRECT RULE...0......OOOOCIOOOOCIOOOOOOOOOO OOOOOOOOOOOO 41 III LABOR RECRUITMENT AND CAPITAL DEVELOPMNT.....OOOOOCCOOCOOOOOOOOICOO0.00......90 IV THE EMERGENCE OF THE IMPERIAL STATE: ECONOMIC CONSOLIDATION.........................l34 V THE RWANDAN COLONIAL ECONOMY: COFFEE PRODUCTION, 1920-1937...OOOCOOCOCOOOOOO ....... .166 VI EXPLOITATION AND CLASS CONSCIOUSNESS...........206 VII THE COLONIAL STATE, EUROPEAN PLANTERS, AND THEMETROPOLE.COOOOOOOOOOCOOOOOO0.0...0.00.246 VIII RETRENCHMENT AND RETROSPECTION.... ........... ..322 CONCLUSION..... ...... ....................................350 APPENDIX I Table A-1. Volume and Value of Imports, 1922-1959. ............ 366-369 II Table B-I(a). Volume of Foreign Trade, 1927-1960 ................... 370-372 III Table C-l. Principle Food Products Exported to the Belgian‘ Congo from Ruanda-Urundi, 1928-1938................. ..... 373-374 IV Table D-l. The Principal Tax Receipts in Rwanda and Burundi, 1925-1959 (in Belgian francs) ............ 375-379 BIBLIOGRAPHY... .......................... . ........... 380-400 vi TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE TABLE II III IV VI VII VIII IX XI XII XIII XIV LIST OF TABLES Coffee Exported from Rwanda and Burundi to Foreign Markets, 1927 to 1938 (in kilos) . . . . . . . Volume of Import and Export Trade in the Belgian Congo, 1925 to 1932 Coffee Production in Eastern Zaire, 1928 to 1933 (in tons) . Percentage and Actual Number of Africans from Rwanda and Burundi at the Union Miniére in Haut Katanga, 1926 to 1930 . Taxes Paid in Belgian Francs in Rwanda Territory in 1928 . . . The Financial Position of Rwanda and Burundi from 1922 to 1931 The Total Number of Agricultural and Commercial Firms in Rwanda, 1923 to 1929 . . . . . . Salaried Employment in 1933 The Principal Tax Receipts in 1932 (in francs) . . . . . . . The Total Number of Coffee Trees Planted During the Campaigns . . Total Number of Hectares Planted in Coffee in 1936 . . . . . Q 9 O O Coffees Imported for Belgian Consumption, 1936 to 1939 (in tons) . Import Duty on Coffees in 1938 (per 100 kilOS) o o o o o o 9 Coffee Cultivation in 1938 vii p 104-104a 106 106 114 114 122 145 185 192 194 275 276 277 282 TABLE XV Total Value of Sales by Europeans and ASian Firms in 1933 o o o o o o o o o o 9 332—335 TABLE XVI Minimum Purchasing Prices for Arabica coffee en parche for Rwanda and Burundi . 348 (in Belgian francs) . . . . . . . . . . viii INTRODUCTION Fifteen to twenty years ago the dialectic of develop- ment and underdevelopment was the near exclusive preserve of left-liberal theorists. Marxist input and influence was only secondary. But today the reverse is true. In fact, since the 1960's, there has been intense debate and even schisms among Marxists and quasi-Marxists over the "new-Marxist paradigm that invaded development studies and has stood apart from both classical Marxism and the liberal sub-discipline of economic development."1 As a result of the debate over this issue no common denominator has yet to be established for the paradigm,2 and some observers have become increasingly alarmed over the possibility of a crisis in Marxist theory if divisions of interests and opinions are not resolved. Still there are those who see the current situations in development studies as constitut- ing a paradigm shift, "because of the difficulty of identi— fying a new-Marxist paradigm and because there has been no major defection of liberals toward any alliance with Marxism." Many insist that the dynamics of development studies is best depicted as the waxing and waning of two quite different traditions,4 each with its own debates and problems, and addressing each other in eye-to-eye confrontation at only a few modal points. Or perhaps the issue could best be described as the pains of an emerging or maturing discipline. The most recent tendency in developmental theory, however, is to see colonialism as a structure and as much more than just political control or colonial policy. Actually, the colonial system incorporated the colonial state,5 and as a variant of the capitalist system, it interacted with the various sectors of the traditional society, and ultimately imposed its hegemony. Almost simultaneously, the state found the means of extracting from the peasant economies the fiscal resources to pay for conquest and for its own institutionalization.6 An analy- sis of the development of the colonial state, therefore, is clearly vital for a fuller understanding of colonialism. Only by understanding the colonial state's most salient feature--its centrality in the political economy through the unusual scope and intensity of its intervention into social and economic 1ife--can we have a much fuller appre- ciation for the dynamics of potential change within the colonial system itself and in the development of capitalism. According to Lonsdale and Berman, the state is the historically conditioned set of institutions which secures the social conditions for the reproduction of the dominant or capitalist mode of production. Capitalism depends on the accumulation of surplus values from labor power in its continuing domination of an ever-changing process of class struggle. But capitalism cannot secure this dominant posi— tion for itself, primarily because of its competitive nature and potential for conflict. Therefore, it relies upon the state to provide the technical and legal conditions for capitalist penetration--i.e., monetary and tariff rules, property laws, social services and of maintaining the hierarchy in class domination.7 They further contend that the state straddles not one but two levels of articulation: between the metropole and the colony as a whole as well as within the colony itself. Because of this duality the colonial state was a subordinate agent in restructuring local production to meet metropolitan demands and the local factor of cohesion over heterogeneous, fragmented and contradictory social forces within its bound- aries. This "Dual Mandate" defined the dilemmas of the colonial state. Since it was obliged to intervene more directly in the economic life of the country than was characteristic of the contemporary capitalist state, it had to absorb these contradictions more directly into the bureaucratic sphere. Consequently, disagreements over colonial development were not between parties but between officials, and when the metropole insisted upon financial self-sufficiency, the colonial state inherited a sovereign self-interest in the orderly expansion of its forces of production.8 As the colonial state proceeded with its task of social engineering, it often had to use force to achieve the extraction of local labor for capitalist production I and to generate peasant production of export crops. More often than not, the state's preoccupation with ensuring conditions of primary accumulation threatened political order. Consequently, the state was frequently forced to seek aCCOmmodation with the subject population in order to govern and to continue the process of primitive accumula- tion. Still the process of articulation raised the dilemma of how far metropolitan interests could be pressed against the interests of local producers in a colony, whether African peasants or European settlers, of, internally, of settlers over Africans, before provoking resistance and undermining effective state control.9 By drawing on the current Marxist debate about the nature of the capitalist state, this thesis argues that during the colonial era, traditional Rwandan social and economic and political institutions underwent profound changes as the colonial states, both German and Belgian, sought to incorporate African production into, the nation- al and then the world economy. This study explores changes from 1916 to 1941, and shows that as the colonial systems organized the traditional society for production and as one of them ultimately achieved its goal, not only was the Rwandan economy severely distorted but traditional Bahutu and Batutsi class alignments were further accentuated. Organizing production required the transformation of the traditional mode of production, described here as the tribute-paying or tributary mode of production, where the peasantry's (the Bahutu) "dominion eminens" over the soil 10 had been lost to feudal or Batutsi lords. The goals of the colonial system were to replace a subsistence economy with a cash economy, to spread Christianity and western education, and to inculcate into Rwandans a western mode of thought concerning government and development. Like it or not, Rwandans experienced escalating socio-economic changes which emanated from vaguely understood sources. These changes had unantici- pated consequences for both Bahutu and Batutsi. They transformed their ideas and manners. How did ordinary Rwandans or the peasantry cope with these changes? What was the range of their options? These questions are ad- dressed here. While the Bahutu peasantry had no control in shaping colonial policy, it would be wrong to conceive of them as disinterested observers or passive objects waiting to be transformed by a new breed of social engineers. Even if the current situation was not of their choosing, they had to adapt their lives to new circumstances, opportunities, and ideas. As commercial agriculture and its infrastructure developed within Rwanda, the demands for salaried labor expanded. New forms of wealth affected the traditional structure in different ways. For the Batutsi oligarchy. the arbiters of the colonial structure, wealth increased power, social stratification, and ethnicity. In fact Newbury, in "The Cohesion of Oppression: A Century of Clientship," also argues that social stratification between Bahutu and Batutsi increased as a result of new economic forms. She contends that employment gave workers, both Bahutu and Batutsi, an opportunity to gain economic inde- pendence and eventually a certain autonomy vis-a-vis the chief. More significantly, colonial rule served as the context for political change that resulted in the emergence of ethnicity, social stratification, and, eventually, organized attempts by oppressed groups to reject Batutsi and, then Belgian domination.11 Newbury demonstrates that these changes occurred in the western periphery, but she minimizes these changes for the central plateau, where coffee production supplemented salaried employment and created similar changes. She con- tends that nowhere in Rwanda had there developed as large a European population or as important an urban center as was found in Bukavu and Kivu Province. In these urban centers emigrant Rwandans from the western periphery were exposed to new experiences and came into contact with ide- ological alternatives which gave them an autonomy from the local political structure--alternatives which were not present in the same form in central Rwanda. But she fails to realize that the modern economy not only generated eco- nomic independence for some Bahutu throughout all of Rwanda, but that it also produced class consciousness and higher expectations. And the Bahutu could only achieve the latter by gaining control of the means of production through a political solutiOn.12 Helen Codere, in "The Biography of an African Society, Rwanda, based on Forty—Eight Rwandan Autobiographies," probably comes closest to a comprehensive analysis of the impact of the money economy on Rwanda. She contends that new economic opportunities were beginning to blur the eco- nomic differentials within each group of Rwanda. In fact, by 1959 the Batutsi as a group were less distinguished by their relative wealth than had formerly been the case. She affirms that as a group they were much better off com- pared to the Bahutu, and that they held a disproportionate number of salaried jobs in civil service and education. But where Bahutu had educational opportunities and quali- fications, they were able to move into salaried employment and into occupations such as teaching. Where they lacked education, they pursued money income through wage labor, including emigration to Uganda for such work and the pro- duction and sale of cash crops.13 Consequently,.coffee production was also instrumental in transforming Rwandan society. The development of coffee as a cash crop was the focus of the changing relationship between the administration, the peasantry, and the Batutsi oligarchy. As a result, this study locates the principal dynamics of the growth of the coffee economy not only within the Belgian colonial state but in the depression of 1929 as well. Following the analysis of B. Jewiewicki, in "The Great Depression and the Making of the Colonial Economic Situation in the Belgian Congo," African Economic History, 4 (Fall 1977), this research shows that the Great Depression was also the most important stage in the elaboration of the Rwandan colonial economic structure, particularly when mounting deficits had to be subsidized by the Metropole. Moreover, the history of Rwandan coffee production falls into three distinct phases, with some overlapping because of external factors. The first lasted from 1920 to 1931, when efforts of colonial administrators met with strenuous Opposition from the ruling Batutsi oligarchy. The latter forced the administration to seek accommodations and once these were accomplished, the second phase commenced. From 1931 to 1937, the administration successfully expanded coffee production among the African peasantry. The third phase, which is not clearly delineated, ended in 1939, when the coffee economy collapsed. In distinguishing the final phase, one must also consider the Opposition to African coffee cultivation from white planters in the rest of Belgian Africa. Their opposition, which surfaced in 1927, contributed to the collapse of the Rwandan coffee economy. Between 1927 and 1939, European planters in Stanleyville, Bukavu, and the Kivu and their representa- tives at Brussels consistently voiced opposition to African 14 Some argued that the terrain commercial cultivation. was not suitable for coffee production, or that transporta— tion to the coasts would make the coffee too expensive and therefore uneconomic. Many maintained that Africans were 15 and that incapable of cultivating such a delicate crop, cotton would be more appropriate for them to grow. A few associations asserted that African participation would increase supply and deflate prices. They also feared that African-grown coffee would confuse marketing procedures and quality controls. Others questioned the rationale of stimulating a luxury crop in an area frequented by disease and famine. A more logical policy, they argued, would be to concentrate African efforts on production to create food reserves and establish exports to neighboring areas such as Katanga. Obviously the real issues were competition and low- cost production. Commercial planters were preoccupied with efforts or schemes to reduce labor costs, increase yields, and attract workers for low wages. Almost any proposal received careful scrutiny,16 and as the Great 10 Depression worsened and budget deficits increased, cost efficiency became more acute. Aside from a solution to the African problem, planters asked government for subsi- dies, tariff reductions, and more regulations to assure even cheaper labor costs, to maximize profits, and to re- duce overhead. Consequently the reaction of colonials are discussed within the context of the metropole's policy pronouncements about African farmers and marketing controls over their production. Thus, the research covers factors within Rwanda and those external to it. Although coffee is the single most important export commodity of Rwanda, only limited research has been done on its production. Various assumptions and descriptions have been made of the industry in both academic circles and institutions involved in making policies that directly affect production and marketing activities. These discus- sions and policy decisions, however, have not considered the role of peasant economies vis-a-vis the colonial eco- nomic structure and the international market systems. For example, Belgian scholars, such as Phillipe Leurquin, H. E. Van Tichelin, and Jacque Lefevre, concen- trate on development and focus on African populations as obstacles in terms of depletion of natural resources, pop- ulation pressures, reliance upon traditional agricultural 17 methods, and general backwardness. They have not placed African economies within the context of the Belgian ll colonial economic system. Nor have they acknowledged the constraints of colonial state domination on African economic development. This study corrects these omissions by uti- lizing data from archives in Rwanda, Belgium, and the United Kingdom and personal interviews conducted in Rwanda from January 1977 to November 1979. The approach presented here, however, relates not to economic history per se, but to social history in its broadest conception--the inter- action of economics, culture, and politics. Economics is made central to the approach by the problematic assertion that economic relations are fundamental but not determin— ing in the process of social evolution and change. INTRODUCTION Notes 1See E. A. Brett, Colonialism and Underdevelopment in East Africa: The Politics of Economic Change, 1919-1939 (New York, 1973; Walter Rodney, How Europe Upderdeveloped Africa (London, 1972); Aidan Foster-Carter, "Neo-Marxist Approaches to Development and Underdevelopment in E. de Kadt and G. Welbans (eds.) §pciology and Development (London, 1974), pp. 67-105; and "From Rostow to Gunder Frank: Conflicting Paradigms in the Analysis of Underdevelopment," World Development, 4 (1976), pp. 67-108. 2Aidan Foster-Carter, "The Modes of Production Controversy," New Left Review, 107 (1978), pp. 47-77. 3Jean Lopans and David Seddon, "Marxism and Anthro- pology: A Preliminary Survey," in D. Seddon (ed.) Relations of Production (London, 1978), pp. 40-41. 4See Richard Heggath's "From Modernization Theory to Public Policy: Continuity and Change in the Political Science of Political Development," paper presented to the 49th ANZAAS Congress, Sociology Section, Auckland, New Zealand, January 1979, where he argues strongly that liberal theories of modernization have not disappeared so much as undergone a change in form. 5Bipan Chandra, "Colonialism, Stages of Colonialism and the Colonial State," Journal of Contemporary Asia, X, no. 3 (1980), p. 273. 6Crawford Young, "Patterns of Social Conflict: State, Class, and Ethnicity," Daedalus, 111, no. 2 (Spring, 1982), p. 75. Bruce J. Berman and J. M. Lonsdale, "Crises of Accumulation, Coercion and the Colonial State: the Develop- ment of the Labor Control System in Kenya, 1919-1929," Canadian Journal of African Studies, XIV, no. 1 (1980), p. 56. 7John M. Lonsdale and Bruce J. Berman, ”Coping with the Contradictions: the Development of the Colonial State in Kenya, 1895-1914," Journal of African History, XX, no. 4 (1979). p. 489. 13 81bid., p. 490. 9Berman and Lonsdale, "Crises of Accumulation," pp. 60-61. 10Samir Amin, Unequal Development: An Essay on the Social Formation of Peripheral Capitalism (New York & London, 1976), p. 13. 11See M. Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression: A Century of Clientship in Kinyaga, Rwanda," (Ph.D. thesis, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1975), pp. 178-179 and 263-266. 12M. Newbury,"0ppressionf' pp. 298-300 and 347 also Fredrik Barth (ed.), Ethnic Groups and Boundaries (Bergen-Oslo, 1969), pp. 9-38. The Rwandan experience conforms to Barth's theory of displacement. When two or more ethnic groups are competing for the same economic resources in the same ecological niche, he contends that one will either be replaced or accommodation involving an increasing complimentarity and interdependence will develop. 13Helen Codere, "The Biography of an African Society, Rwanda; based on Forty-Eight Rwandan Autobiographies," Institut National de Recherche Scientifique (Butare), No. 12, (1973). Reprise d'une publication du Musee Royal de l'Afrique Centrale, Tervuren, p. 37. 14Agriculture et Elevaqe au Congo Belge, ll, 2 (December, 1928), p. 315; VI, 14 (October 15, 1932); VI, p. 16 (November 26, 1932), pp. 183-6; and VII, 1 (January, 1934), p. 3. 15African Archives. Agri. 340, Dossier 207. MinistEre des Colonies. Note pour la 6§me Directeur Générale. Brussels, February 17, 1932; and Dossier 208, MinistEre des Colonies. Note pour Monsieur le Ministre. Brussels, February 19, 1932. 16"Documentation sur le Kivu et le Ruanda-Urundi," Agriculture et Elevaqe au Congo Belge, VI, 16 (November 26, 1932). PP. 183-6. 17See Leurquin, "La Vie Economique du Paysan Ruanda, 1'exemple de Karama, Nyaruguru," Zaire, 11 (January 1957); Van Tickelin, "ProblEmes du Développement Economique du Ruanda-Urundi," Zaire, 11, (May 1957) and Lefevre, Structures Ecgpomiques du Congo Belge et du Ruanda-Urundi (Brussels, 1955). I X. \1 I o o\ s“ K\ I III‘".\\|-" ) \ \. . ”A 1‘ I) \~ ~ /. <- z20 / V a t , .1 l./ f ’ o O L 01' \u ’\u l f. \ / .S’xa 3002092 F .Il‘. ’ a w 143 s”. 00:39:. N .\ .. \ g a .K 9.55520 .>sow ma Hum Wusmmoumuuommmm "momDOm .moHHx mo Omoumcfl msou cH« i on i u i u u pasmm Hum.m emm.ms eme.a u meH i u peeps: . mes OOH as me i u morphs eee.aa u a m a one .33 omeoo cmemamm u i oom u i u eeo.~ massacre oee.e es~.H~ emo.e sas.efi moe.e mHH.m meo.e shoueuhme wresemmcms www.mm ems mmm.mm mee Has.m~ me~.m~ mfle.e enemamm mmms mmmfl Hmmfl ones ewes mama sums shucsoo inches rev mmmaismmfi .mumrhmz amemhom on epcshsm paw mpcmzm sown pmuuonxm mommoo .H wanes .meH .a .mmmH phoneme “men one ems .ea .emms uhommmm isms can mma .an .mmmH whonmmm .mma pee Hes .meH .ae .mmma phoneme ammH pee ems .meH .mn .emma phoneme "momSOm 104 A om~.om i i I i mmumum Omuwco on i i i I xumscmo i i ow ow I usuHmcm i i I i I . Damon mmm.a>~ I I I I spasm: i i i oso.m OOH morphs u om~.H ooe.s ~m~.- ems.mm omeoo cmemsmm on~.m i i I i “shamans oee.~sm ONH mme.sfi ~me.a~ eHe shouehhms arescmmema omm.~me.m emm.oefi.~ are.sm~.fl mme.mee meo.sfim sssmamm mmma smmfl emmfl . mmma emma mhucsoo ..moaes as. mmmsismma .hpcshsm new hpcmsm some pmuuomxm mmumoo .H wanes 105 in Zaire (or Congo) was to create an infrastructure that would continue to attract foreign finance and industrial capital. A5 a result of the infusion of capital, the Congo experienced an economic boom between 1923 and 1930, which increased production and modernized the extractive indus- tries, expanded the rail network and facilitated construc- tion, and agricultural production. Exports were valued at 628,573,946BF in 1925 and 1,511,490,87lBF in 1930 (see Table II, Volume Of Imports and Exports Trade, 1925 to 1932). COpper production rose from 56,221 metric tons in 1923 to 138,949 tons in 1930. The production of diamonds rose from 318,979 carats in 1920 to 2,518,258 carats in 1930. Cotton, palm oil, palm kernels, and coffee exports also experienced notable increases. Of the agricultural exports, cotton was exclusively an African prerogative, although the processing was confined solely to Europeans. Palm Oil and coffee production were left to European producers,43 who were well established in eastern Zaire by 1925, especially in the Kivu and Ituri, with 1200 hectares and 1000 hectares respectively under cultivation. As indicated in Table III, coffee production continued to increase despite the depression and declining world market prices and consumption (see Table III, coffee Production in Eastern Zaire, 1928-1933). Competition from African planters would therefore encounter strenuous resistance when compulsory coffee cultivation 106 Table II. Volume Of Imports and Export Trade in the Belgian Congo, 1925 to 1932.1 Year Imports Exports Metric Value in Metric Value in Tons Francs Tons Francs 1925 524,853 876,245,151 213,242 628,573,946 1926 631,584 1,293,197,242 203,678 729,301,977 1927 649,586 1,496,358,868 223,266 1,055,239,249 1928 736,054 1,624,498,658 257,633 1,227,867,419 1929 814,553 1,943,192,906 300,333 1,444,266,477 1930 712,286 1,581,315,177 340,317 1,511,490,871 1931 356,640 961,891,851 273,373 1,104,045,231 1932 182,878 464,631,939 206,240 667,922,436 SOURCE: Department of Overseas Trade. NO. 565, Economic Situation in the Belgian Congo and the Territories of Ruanda-Urundi to August, 1933. Reported by Harold C. Swan, Consul-General, Leopoldville (London, 1934), p. 11. 1Figures do not include transit traffic. Table III. Coffee Production in Eastern Zaire, 1928 to 1933. (in tons) Year Kivu Ituri Total 1928 64 119 183 1929 108 140 243 1930 699 161 800 1931 643 201 844 1932 793 305 1,098 1933 1,005 429 1,434 SOURCE: Raymond Brock, "Le Cafe’ Arabica et le Kivu," Agriculture et Elevage au Congo Belge, NeuviEme année, NO. 11 (January, 1935), p. 2. 107 was introduced in Rwanda during the 19305. Despite increased agricultural production in Zaire, the bulk of the country's economic growth and capital was in its extractive industries. Naturally, this kind of eco- nomic emphasis did not favor the development of either an autonomous African capitalist class or a class of petty European traders and commercial capitalists. In fact, African areas were subjected to severe shocks: traditional structures in the vicinity of capitalistic growth lost pop- ulation, and in some places the demographic balance was severely distorted. Also, excessive recruiting destroyed the basis of the traditional apportionment of work between Old and young, male and female.44 More than a million African peasants were also subjected to a levy on their agriculture-surplus.45 In western Shaba, the African cat- tle industry was practically wiped out by an administration that wished to see cattle husbandry in European hands.46 Paradoxically, however, colonial Officials did not generally welcome European settlers and petty traders. In the early 19205, European settlements were halted, primar- ily because the colons had failed to carry their own weight. The economic slump after World War I bankrupted many of them. Other farming enterprises failed because of the high cost of machinery and the inability of draught animals to survive the tsetse fly. The high level of industrial wages also made it impossible for European farmers to procure 108 47 But it may very well labor at a cost they could afford. have been that their role in the colony was more political than economic. Since the dominant policy of the state was to actively encourage large capital enterprises, an econo- my based On the extensive exploitation of African labor by industrial and commercial firms made it difficult for Euro- pean agriculture to compete with big business in labor re- cruiting or with African cultivators in price advantage. European settlers only survived with the benefit of gov- ernment subsidies and with a monopoly over some branches of production, such as dairy farming, fresh vegetables and fruits, poultry and pork for a European clientele, and the cultivation of Robusta coffee. The production of fresh agricultural produce was quite profitable for both Euro- peans and Africans in Zaire as well as Rwanda, especially for those living near the commercial, industrial, and ad- ministrative centers along the routes of communication. But in the beginning difficulties in transport limited the geographical extension of commercial agricultural produce.48 The European enterprises, however, were maintained for political reasons in peripheral regions, like Kivu, and on the fringes Of the larger urban areas. Their presence validated Belgium's possession of the colony at a time when Greeks and other foreigners were numerically superior.49 Large capitalist undertakings, especially UMHK, were nurtured by the state, and they relied upon European firms 109 from eastern Zaire and Rwanda to provide food for the mines. In eastern Zaire, European settlers.had arrived just after the war, and high prices for primary products encouraged many to invest in farming. Consequently, large plantations in coffee, cotton, and palm oil were developed in the 19205, especially on the fertile soil of Kivu. Settlers in Katanga and Ituri, however, established large scale stock-raising and dairy enterprises. Some farmers also specialized in Arabica coffee production, particularly those in Haut-Ituri.50 Mostly, however, farmers throughout eastern Zaire produced fresh fruit and vegetables, pork and poultry for Europeans. The European population increased slowly, but the Kivu experienced the most rapid growth because of its appealing climate, soil fertility, and altitude. In 1925, the Euro- pean pOpulation was 190; it rose to 650 by 1928, and by 51 1931 the population was over 1,000. In the same period, the total area used for agriculture doubled to 24,000 hectares and coffee production quintupled (see Table III).52 Europeans in these areas had very little difficulty re- cruiting non-skilled labor for their farms and industries. In fact, administrators in Kivu Province, and during the 19305 in Bukavu Province, used Cyangugu territory in Rwanda as a labor pool. Labor recruitment from these areas was quite intense from 1926 to 1929. Demands for labor were so heavy that the administration in Kivu was forced to 110 close several areas to recruitment. Settlers in the Kivu also wrote to Kigali requesting permission from the resi- dent to recruit workers in Cyangugu.53 During the 19205, economic conditions in Rwanda were still underdeveloped, except around Lake Kivu and Kinyaga. Firms and settlers in these areas required African labor. The lack of development in the rest of the country was caused by an absence of infrastructure and capital invest- ment. The majority of European firms Operating in Rwanda were concerned with either commerce or agriculture.54 Most confined their operations to western Rwanda, near cyangugu, in the north to Ruhengeri and Kisenyi, and on the 55 Administrators Central Plateau to Kigali and Butare. made every effort to facilitate labor recruiting in these regions. The largest employer during this period was the Protanag, or the Société Coloniale de Produits Tonnants et Agricoles, with a staff of nineteen Europeans by 1929, and 56 The com- capital assets of 12.5 million francs in 1928. pany initially planted coffee, but gradually introduced black walnut trees to be exploited for tannin. By 1929 the company employed 1500 Rwandans from the Kinyaga area. Its recruiting efforts were confined to Lusungu and Kibazi (in present-day Kamembe and Karengera communes, respectively), and approximately 80 percent of the avail- able men in these areas were employed by the company. 111 Towards 1929, the Compagnie de la Ruzizi began to intro- 57 Also duce cotton in the Bugarama region of Kinyaga. there was the additional attraction for labor from Kinyaga, because of the expansion Of plantations and mines in Kivu Province.58 Concessions in Cyangugu and Kigali also planted coffee and food crops.59 Société Plantations du Tanganyika, with capital assets Of 1 million francs, ini- tiated coffee cultivation in both Rwanda and Burundi. This particular company sought to improve cultivation by establishing nurseries and seed selection. It also ex- pressed a desire to improve exportation methods through the creation of an agency to oversee the sorting and clas- sification of coffee. Eventually, the company hoped to Open a processing mill, provided it could interest other companies in a shared-cost agreement.60 This procedure suggests that some companies either lacked adequate finan- ces to expand rapidly, or tried to moderate risks through shared ventures. A 1929 Report, outlining the recruitment procedure used by UMHK, Protanag, and Forminiére, noted that UMHK employed about fifty Africans per day, while Protanag used from 60 to 100 men daily, and Forminiére, employed about 400 men per day. Although the first two companies did not receive any direct assistance from the administration at Nyanza in recruiting laborers, workers arrived at the Protanag camp, about four kilometers from the district 112 post at Nyanza each morning to offer their services. UMHK had official sanction to recruit from territorial authorities. Contractual workers reported directly to various district posts, where they were informed of the essential points of their contractual obligations. But Forminiére, responsible for the construction of Ndeza road, received even more assistance from Belgian officials, when they directed notables to furnish five percent of the tax- payers for the stretches of road passing through their particular hill. Upon completion of the project, the Bahutu returned to their fields without disturbing the planting cycle.61 African salaries were low, despite the administra- tion's assertion that wages were increasing along with the 62 While skilled influx of Africans into the labor force. workers like masons, carpenters, and chauffeurs might re- ceive 1,0008F per month, workers in other categories rare- ly received more than 400 francs per month. Clerks and/or servants received a monthly salary of less than 300 francs: unskilled laborers received a uniform rate of l.SOBF with- out rations. Carrier or head porters, who had not declined significantly despite efforts to create an infrastructure, received between 3.4SBF and 4.9SBF, which included the ration allowance for the trip.63 Laborers employed in the construction of roads and other public works projects re- ceived one franc per day. Private companies paid their 113 workers between l.SOBF and 2.0BF per day.64 Bahutu who hired themselves out to other Rwandans received one to two francs per day. But most Often they worked for food which had to be shared with their families. For five hours work, they might receive from one to one and a half kilos of beans 65 With the ex- or perhaps three kilos of sweet potatoes. ception of the skilled labor category, and considering that African purchasing power diminished between 1922 and 1929 because of inflation and currency devaluation and depreci- ation, wages in 1929 did not differ substantially from V those in 1924. In that year, carriers received 0.6OBF per day for a load of 25 kilos, day workers one franc, and spe- cialists or skilled laborers from 1.258F to 7BF per day.66 Nor did wage rates for 1929 reflect the inflated value of commercial exports between 1922 and 1929 (see Appendix I). Although the volume of exports declined in certain years during this period, the value of exports increased 14.6 times from 1922 to 1929. The dominant recruiter in Rwanda was the Union Miniére du Haut Katanga. Between 1925 and 1930, the company re- cruited more than 10,900 Africans from Rwanda and Burundi 67 to work in the mines (see Table IV). On the average, 12 percent of the total work force came from the territor- ies of Rwanda and Burundi, especially from Ruhengeri, Kisenyi, Kabaya, Kigali, Butare, Gatsibu, and Rukira 68 Territories, where, in 1928, people paid the highest 114 Table IV. Percentage and Actual Number of Afrigans from Rwanda and Burundi at the Union Miniere in Haut Katanga, 1926-1930 Year Total Work Force Ruanda-Urundi Percentage 1926 13,200 1,101a 8a 1927 15,400 1,300 8 1928 15,900 1,300 1929 16,500 2,500 15 1930 15,700 4,700 30 SOURCE: John E. Higginson, "The Making of an African Work- ing Class," p. 292. NOTES: aCAMP. Rwanda. Miscellaneous Archival Material, 1925-1941. Rapport Annual (n.d.) DéVeloppement Moral et Social des IndigEnes. 3e Partie: Protection du Travail. Table V. Taxes Paid in Belgian Francs in Rwanda Territory in 1928. Territory Tax Payment Territory Tax Payment (francs) (francs) Butare 57,000fb Cyangugu 24,000fb Nyanza 50,000fb Rikiro 32,000fb Kigali 50,000fb Lubengera 22,000fb Ruhengeri 46,000fb Kabaya 15,000fb Gatsibu 39,000fb Kisenyi 12,000fb SOURCE: John E. Higginson, "The Making of an African Work- ing Class," p. 301. 115 taxes. The two exceptions (see Table V), Kabaya and Kisenyi, were not brought under administrative control until rather late in the colonial period. During the fam- ine in the late 19205, large numbers also came from cen- tral and eastern Rwanda, areas most severely affected, to seek work at Katanga. After 1930, the number of Bahutu employed by Union Minisre declined dramatically from 2,500 in 1931 to barely 400 at the beginning of 1932.69 While the depression affected the need for labor, recruitment in Rwanda also declined because of the success of Union Miniére's stabili- zation program, the demand for labor in Rwanda and its peripheries in the east and the west, the eagerness of Belgian officials to increase the pace of development in Rwanda, and international pressure from the League of Nations,70 whose potential for criticism forced the Bel- gians to proceed cautiously. The stabilization policy, introduced in 1928, in- volved the permanent settlement of workers and their fami- lies in the neighborhood of the mines. Workers were sup- plied with houses, medical services, and free education for their children as inducements to remain in the area or to sign new contracts. A graduated scale Of wages was introduced and a training program to produce skilled work- ers was also implemented. As a result of the policy, dur- ing the first year, turnover was reduced about a third, 116 and in 1929, 45 percent of the labor force was stabilized:71 Whereas the average demand for recruits between 1921 and 1929 had been about 10,000 men a year, the number declined to an annual average of 1800 between 1935 and 1942.72 By 1932, the policy was a dramatic success story, since the Officials at the mines were able to announce that they no longer needed recruits from Rwanda and Burundi.73 The decline of Rwandan recruits for the mines at Katanga also coincided with the emergence of Bukavu as a center of service and supply for settlers in the Kivu and Kinyaga. Naturally, as a result, the flow of workers shifted from Katanga to these areas; it was much closer to home and wages were much better. Laborers were needed to build and maintain buildings in Bukavu and to work as skilled and semi-skilled workers in the trades, where their services were in great demand by the industries of the town. As we have already noted, the large number of European plantations in the vicinity added to heavy labor demands and workers from other areas of Rwanda, and especially Kinyaga, were called on to supplement the local labor supply:74 Naturally, wages were low: in 1926 pay varied from 7BF to 60BF per month. The latter was exceptional and generally reserved for gang or crew chiefs. But in addition to salaries, some workers might receive daily rations and a jacket and blanket each year. Those who worked on a daily basis might receive from 25 to 50 117 centimes, but generally not rations.75 Despite low wages, the economic connection between Rwanda and these areas would continue to grow from the 19305 onward, and the eco- nomic impact between the Kivu, Kinyaga, and surrounding areas would be tremendous. Administrative personnel recog- nized this fact when they announced in 1938 that Cyangugu Territory was in the Kivu's sphere, and that the Territory 76 The supplied it with manpower and diverse products. 1939-44 Report would also note that there had been a pro- gressive transformation of African activity in the region west of Cyangugu, where many Africans devoted themselves to petty trade or gave their services to large enterprises.77 By 1947, 30 percent of the African adult male population were employed by European establishments at Bukavu and by colonists at Cyangugu.78 The major occupation of Rwandans on the periphery, besides meeting the demands of the administration and European establishments for labor, was producing food and livestock for European firms for export to the mining cen- ters in eastern Zaire, to include Bukavu and the Kivu. As early as 1917, western Rwanda had acquired importance as a 79 provisioning center for parts of Zaire. By 1923, there were some 27 firms Operating in the area; most were con- cerned with either commerce or agriculture.80 Approxi- mately 50 to 80 percent of the exports in the 19205 con- sisted of foodstuffs (Appendix II and III). In 1922, for 118 example, 2,232 tons of food were exported, and in 1923, 6,647 tons.81 That year the Belgian Congo received 4,728 tons Of food, including peas, beans, maize flour, rice, manioc flour, and maize. Officials were particularly en- thusiastic about the potential of manioc and maize, because production of the former had doubled between 1922 and 1923, and the latter from one ton in 1922 to more than 700 tons in 1923, as a result of intensive cultivation. They were convinced that this kind of output would virtually assure Rwanda's and Burundi's role as a food center for Katanga,82 which received almost all of the maize flour. In 1925, 2,615 tons of food were transported to the Congo;83 and in 1947, 4,641 tons of food and 1,444 head of livestock were exported there. The following year some 1,260 tons of food, including coffee, tobacco, mats, and graisse indigéne, and 1,438 head Of livestock went to the Congo.84 But in 1929, the volume of food exported was only 368 tons, including manufactured products, and 1,146 head Of live animals.85 The years 1928 and 1929 were of particular signifi- cance; provisions were exported to the Congo when Rwanda was in the midst of a famine. The problem of scarcity had appeared as early as 1926, when food production began to decline. Also, the demand for porters and laborers forced many cultivators to leave their plots, and in 1927 insuf- ficient rainfall brought the first signs of scarcity to 119 eastern Rwanda. Despite these signs, the officials con- tinued to requisition labor and to ship food to the Belgian Congo.86 By 1931, the volume of exports to the Congo was more than 4,000 tons out of a total production of 5,307 tons.87 In 1932, total exports surpassed the 1927 level-- 7,286 tons in 1932 versus 6,409 tons in 1927. Local pro- duce shipped to Zaire amounted to 5,600 tons and 70,132 88 As Rwanda's agri- head of livestock and 3,600 chickens. cultural production recovered in the 19305 and as the civil administration became more consolidated, Rwanda's O O I \ O I pOSltlon as a grenier a Vivres became an important compo- nent of the overall agricultural policy, which consisted of regularizing food production, introducing commercial 89 TO implement crops, and improving pastoral potential. these programs, the administration established a Service de l'Agriculture and distributed about a dozen agronomes throughout the different Territories of Rwanda. However, this commitment to the colony's development created an obvious dilemma for Belgian authorities--how to facilitate internal development and to meet the demands for labor by capitalistic centers on the periphery without reducing badly needed capital. To comply with these conflicting needs, Governor Voisin and succeeding administrators sought to eliminate abuses and relax traditional dues rather than restrict or reduce labor recruiting or demands for labor. Voisin, in 120 fact, told his Officials to enforce existing labor protec- tion laws, which were designed to protect the health and security of Rwandans.90 He also recommended that the law Of 4 March 1929, which made the resident responsible for recruitment of labor in his territory, be "strictly" enforced. Residents were also responsible for making sure that workers recruit- ed for Katanga, as required by law, passed through the 21- day indoctrination center at Kitega in Burundi, to receive I O O I O 91 vaCCinations, phySical examinations, 92 and, during the 19205, screening for aptitude. In various decrees in 1930, additional labor rights and employer restrictions were promulgated that refined the basic labor contract law 93 In 1939, Officials took a major step Of 16 March 1922. by permitting six categories of workers to buy Off their traditional Obligations owed to their chiefs. The admin- istration also excused workers whose work "contributed to development." The categories included contract workers, farmers with at least ten head of cattle, students attend- ing school, and mission catechists. Also, those who worked for the administration and seasonal workers absent from their homes at least nine months Of the year were excused. In 1944, this principle of "ransom" was applied to all categories of workers, and henceforth notables were obliged, at least theoretically, to pay cash in return for services performed.94 121 Through the control and recruitment of labor, Belgian authorities were able to force Rwandans out of the tradi- tional sector and into the modern economy. In doing so, they were able to facilitate the development of capital, which ensured the solvency of the colony and built the necessary infrastructure. Salaried employment also enabled Rwandans to pay taxes and to purchase imported goods. It also meant that Africans would assume a greater burden for the development of the colony, as the ratio between local revenues and subsidies from the metropole from 1922 to 1931 indicated (see Table VI). While some Bahutu could manipu- late the labor system to their advantage in terms of cur- rency speculation, food production, and work in British territories, the majority had very few options. To refuse to comply with labor demands meant retribution from the notables, who had a greater degree of discretionary power because of their role as the administration's men, and from the administrators at the district post, who were re- sponsible for getting Africans into the modern economy, be- cause surplus capital had to be developed at any cost. Nor did the increased demands for labor from the administration and from European enterprises produce a corresponding in- crease in African wages. The administration maintained an artificially low wage structure in order to maintain and encourage European investment in the colony. Quite often any gains from wage increases were offset by inflation and Table VI. 122 from 1922 to 1931. The Financial Position of Rwanda and Burundi Year Public Debt Advances from Abroad Total Revenues (francs) (francs) (francs) 1922 -- 1,000,000 2,931,241 1923 -- 1,200,000 3,424,792 1924 -- 1,200,000 5,084,317 1925 -- 3,400,000 7,044,317 1926 -— 5,300,000 10,548,091 1927 -- 5,700,000 15,381,689 1928 -- 4,000,000 23,381,689 1929 -- 11,873,334 26,157,073 1930 6,500,000 14,704,369 30,946,848 .1931 35,000,000 18,438,830 34,277,256 SOURCE: Department of Overseas Trade. 565. Economic Situation in the Belgian Congo and the Terri- tories of Ruanda-Urundi to August, 1933. Reported by Harold C. Swan, Consul-General, Leopoldsville (London, 1934), pp. 64-65. 123 currency depreciations. For example, in 1926, rising prices caused by the sudden decline of the franc during the months of May-June curtailed African purchases of imported goods.95 Even internal disasters did not diminish the admin- istration's zeal to recruit labor and collect taxes. Dur- ing the first year of the famine, Union MiniEre emerged as the dominant recruiter in Rwanda. Despite serious food shortages, the administration continued to permit the ex- port of food to eastern Zaire, and as Appendix IV demon; strates, local revenues continued to increase during the years of the famine. These factors confirm that the Rwandan peasants were tools of the state, and that their decision-making power and alternative choices were severely limited by the demands of Belgian officials and the civil- ian administration or the Batutsi oligarchy. The demand for African labor and the famine were in- strumental in the integration of Rwandans into the capital— ist peripheries of Eastern Zaire, western Rwanda, and British East Africa. Supplying labor to these areas was an integral part of Rwanda's economic program throughout the colonial period. But it nonetheless created a dilemma for colonial planners, who sought to stimulate development while simultaneously using the colony as a labor and food reservoir for the rest of Belgian Africa. Since restric- ting labor recruitment would diminish the development of 124 capital, the only alternative left to the administrators was to expand local agricultural production in order to increase capital and to achieve greater efficiency with a minimal cost to the metropole and disruption to the capi— talist centers on the peripheries of the colony. NOTES TO CHAPTER THREE 1European authorities in Zaire were given a similar order in the form of a circular issued in 1922, which emphasized the duty of officials to give all necessary aid to private enterprises. However, "if moral authority, encouragement, and favors failed, then marks of displea- sure were to be imposed." Lord Hailey, An African Survey: A Study of Problems Arising in Africa_South of the Sahara (London, 1938), p. 645. M. Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression: A Century of Clientship in Kinyaga, Rwanda," (Ph.D. thesis, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1975), pp. 272 and 278. Newbury also notes that the growth of plantations and other enterprises in both Kinyaga and Kivu Province contributed to the progressive augmentation of the labor force. Labor demands for European establish— ments in western Zaire competed with demands from Euro- peans in Kinyaga. The development of urban centers at Bukavu (opposite Cyangugu in Rwanda) from 1930 and higher wages paid in Bukavu and Kivu in general added to the labor drain on Kinyaga. 2Bogumil Jewsiewicki, "Zaire Enters the World System: Its Colonial Incorporation as the Belgian Congo, 1885— 1960," in Zaire: The Political Economy of Underdevelop: ment, eds. Guy Cran and Galen Hull (New York, 1979), p. 31. 3Ian Linden with Jane Linden, Church and Revolution in Rwanda (New York, 1977), p. 166. 4Consortium for Africa Microfilm Project (hereafter CAMP). MF1442. Rwanda. Miscellaneous archival material, 1925-1941. Rapport annuel (U.D.). Developpement moral et social des indigEnes. 36 Partie: Protection du Travail. 5O. Dak, A Geographical Analysis of the Distribution of Migrants in Uganda (Makerere, 1968), pp. 5-6. 6P. S. Powesland, "History of the Migration in Uganda," in Economic Development and Tribal Change: A Study of Immigrant Labor in Buganda, ed. Audrey D. Richards Cambridge, 1954), pp. 49-50. Linden, Church and Revolution, pp. 188 and 206. 125 126 7CAMP. Rwanda. Miscellaneous Archival Material, 1925-1941. Rapport annuel (U.D.). Developpement moral et social des indigEnes. 3§ Partie: Protection du Travail. 8Powesland, "History of the Migration in Uganda," p. 51. 9John E. Higginson, "The Making of an African Work— ing Class: The Union Miniére du Haut Katanga and the African Mine Workers, 1907-1945," (Ph.D. thesis, Univer- sity of Michigan, 1979), p. 296. He also notes that by November 1928, the recruitment of Rwandans had become an integral component of Union Miniére's plan to achieve labor stabilization in Zaire. Also, recruitment in Rwanda accomplished several short-term objectives for the company: it enabled the company to recruit more tractable African workers on long-term contracts (for three years), thus ensuring a more stabilized work force. It also eased the company's dependency on African labor from Northern Rhodesia, who commanded and agitated for higher wages. 10Charlotte Leubuscher, Tanganyika Territory: A Study of Economic Policy Under Mandate (London, 1944), pp. 9-10 and 57. She remarks that the shortage of African labor experienced by Tanganyika's mines and agricultural employ- ers produced an appreciable rise in African wages. In the mines, the average monthly wage rose from 15/61 in 1935 to 17/30 Shs in 1938. 11Higginson, "The Making of an African Working Class," 121bid., pp. 295-296. 13Hailey, An African Survey, p. 645. 14CAMP. Rwanda. Miscellaneous Archival Material, 1925-1941. Rapport annuel (U.D.). Developpement moral et social des indigEnes. 36 Partie: Protection du Travail. 15CAMP. Congo Manuscripts. J. M. Derscheid Collec- tion. MF No. 34, Reel 3. Territoire de Nyanza. Rapport en response au questionnaire par le Gouverneur, 1929, p. 72. CAMP. Rwanda. Miscellaneous Archival Material, 1925-1941. Rapport annuel (U.D.). Developpement moral et social des indigenes. 36 Partie: Protection du Travail. 127 16CAMP. Rwanda. Miscellaneous Archival Material, 1925-1941. Rapport annuel (U.D.). Developpement moral et social des indigEnes. 36 Partie: Protection du Travail. 17Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," pp. 282-283. laIbid. 191bid., pp. 285-286. 20Ibid., p. 287. 21David J. Vail, "The Public Sector as Stimulus of Innovation Adoption in African Smallholder Agriculture: A Case Study in Teso District, Uganda," (Ph.D. thesis, Yale University, 1971), pp. 19-20. Walter Elkan, Migrants and Proletarians: Urban Labour in the Economic Development of Uganda (London, 1960), p. 18. 22Jamal Vali, "The Role of Cotton and Coffee in Uganda's Economic Development" (Ph.D. thesis, Stanford University, 1976), pp. 67-68. C. C. Wrigley, Crops and Wealth in Uganda: A Short Agrarian History (Kampala, 1959), pp. 37-41. Wrigley notes that while European plantations would remain a valuable ingredient in Uganda's economy, they could not become its principal substance. Africans had lower overhead costs and "more modest expec- tations." 23Walter Elkan, The Economic Development of Uganda (London, 1961), pp. 26-28. 24Harry A. Reed, "Cotton-Growing in Central Nyanza Province, Kenya, 1901-1939: An Appraisal of African Reactions to Imposed Government Policy" (Ph.D. thesis, Michigan State University, 1975), pp. 43-44. 25CAMP. -Rwanda. Miscellaneous Archival Material, 1925-1941. Rapport annuel (n.d.). Developpement moral et social des indigEnes. 3é’Partie: Protection du Travail. 26A. I. Richards, "The Travel Routes and the Trav- ellers," in Economic Development and Tribal Change, p. 53; see Jean-Pierre Chretien, "Des Sedentaires Devenus Migrants: les motifs des departs des Burundais et des Rwandais vers l'Uganda (1920-1960)," Culture et devel- oppement, X, n. l (1978), pp. 77-78. Chretien maintains that Kibungu in eastern Rwanda was most affected by departure of emigrants. This region was also closest to the British territories and was the most affected by fre- quent drought. The western region was the least affected 128 because of the distance and because the area was more productive than the eastern region. Moreover, there were more ways to obtain money, since the area was more developed. 27Richards, "The Travel Routes and the Travellers," pp. 53-54. 28Powesland, "History of Migration in Uganda," pp. 39-40. 291bid., pp. 29-30 and 33. 30Dak, Migrants in Uganda, p. 1. When most arrived, they were generally malnourished, ill-dressed, worn out and often ill. Chretien, "Des Sedentaires Devenus Migrants," p. 80. 31 Elkan, Migrants and Proletarians, p. 21. 32 p. 41. 33 Powesland, "History of Migration in Uganda," Dak, Migrants in Uganda, pp. 7-8. 34Powesland, "History of Migration in Uganda," pp. 36-38. 35Dak, Migrants in Uganda, pp. 7-8. 36Bruce Fetter, The Creation of Elizabethville, 1910-1940 (Stanford, 1976), pp. 144-145. The author notes that between 1906 and 1926, the metropole intervened on behalf of Union MiniEre, both politically and financially, a half dozen times. But, during the boom of the late 19203, the power relationship was reversed, as the colonial government became increasingly dependent on the copper industry for revenue. In fact, Fetter remarks that Union Miniere was responsible for 18 percent of colonial receipts in 1926, 24 percent in 1930, and 32 percent in 1932. 37Jewsiewicki, "Unequal Development," p. 322. He notes that the constant demand for food during the 1920s and the desire to make the Katanga economy less dependent on the south forced Haut-Katanga Industrial (hereafter HKI) to search for supplies in the areas opened up to Chemin de fer des Grands lacs Africains and the Kambove-Bukama rail- ways: Lomami, Tanganyika, Moero, Orientale Province, and Ruanda-Urundi. Between 1921 and 1925 supplies from these areas increased by 18 percent. 129 38Jean-Phillipe Peemans, "Capital Accumulation in the Congo Under Colonialism: The Role of the State," in Colonialism in Africa, Vol. Four, (eds.) L. H. Gann and Peter Duignan (Cambridge, 1975), pp. 170-177; George Martelli, Leopold to Lumumba: A History of the Belgian Congo (LondOn, 1962), pp. 194 and 196; and Roger Anstey, King Leopold's Legacy: The Congo Under Belgian Rule, 1908-1960 (London and New York, 1966), p. 102. Supplying the Allies with raw materials during the First World War stimulated the Congo's economy. Commercial activity in- creased as well. The annual output of copper at Katanga increased from 7,400 tons in 1913 to 27,500 tons in 1917. Consequently profits from the war enabled the Union Miniere to pay a small dividend for the first time. The collapse of the commodities market, however, caught the Congo with accumulated stocks, which forced the price of copper to drop as low as 670 a ton at the end of 1920. In fact, mines throughout the world began to close down. But the Board of Directors in Brussels instituted a re- development plan and doubled output to reduce the cost of production. They increased capital and installed new plant equipment. Their program succeeded, and by 1921 Katanga had become the biggest producer of copper in the world. Even though the price of copper had fallen to 657 a ton, the company was still able to show a profit. Also, gold production increased to the point that the Kilo-Moto mines in Orientale Province became a major world producer. 39Anstey, King Leopold's Legacy, p. 103. 40Jewsiewicki, "Zaire Enters the World System," p. 40. 41 Anstey, King Leopold's Legagy, pp. 103-105; Martelli, Leopold to Lumumba, p. 85. 42Jean-Luc Vellut, ”Rural Poverty in Western Shaba, c. 1890-1930," in The Roots of Rural Poverty in Central and Southern Africa, (eds.) Robin Palmer and Neil Parsons (Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1977), p. 305. 43 Anstey, King Leopold's Legacy, pp. 106-107. 4Agriculture et Elevage au Congo Belge, Deuxiéme année, no. 18 (September 8, 1928), p. 211. 45Peemans, "Capital Accumulation in the Congo'" 130 46 p. 305. 47 Vellut, "Rural Poverty in Western Shaba," Jewsiewicki, "Unequal Development," p. 323. 48Jewsiewicki, ”Zaire Enters the World System," pp. 37-38. 49Bogumil Jewsiewicki, "Le Colonat Agricole Europeen au Congo Belge, 1910-1960: Questions Politiques et Economiques," Journal of African History, XX, No. 4 (1979), pp. 559-571. This article is drawn from his thesis. He goes on to say that colons lacked political influence, in the colony at least, until 1945, when they obtained statu- tory participation in the provincial assemblies. Prior to this date, Belgians living in Africa did not have the right to vote in Belgium. Only the large companies ac- tively participated in the political process in Belgium, and only they manipulated parliament and approved policies applicable abroad. Large companies controlled the activi— ties of colons in areas under their control. For example, the Regie des mines d'or de Milo-Moto had jurisdiction over the colons in Ituri. These companies needed workers and cheap food; they did not want the creation of local political forces able to break the tradition of non- interference from the colonial state in their affairs. 50Jewsiewicki, "Le Colonat Agricole Européen au Congo Belge," p. 562; Martelli, Leopold to Lumumba, p. 196. 51Raymond Brock, "Le Café Arabica et le Kivu," Agriculture et Elevage au Congo Belge, NeuviEme année, No. 1 (January 1935), p. 2. 52Jewsiewicki, "Le Colonat Agricole Europeen au Congo Belge," p. 562. x 53 M. Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," pp. 280- 281. 54Rapport presente par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société’, 1927, pp. 79- 80; Rapport presenté’ par le Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société, 1928, p. 91. 55Annuaire Officiel du Ministére des Colonies—-de Bel i ue (Brussels, 1926), p. 945; Annuaire Officiel du Ministere des Colonies--de Belgique (Brussels, 1928), p. 649, Rapportypresenté par le Gouvernement Belge au Consei1 de la Société, 1929, p. 117. 131 56Annuaire Officiel du Ministére des Colonies-~de Belgique (Brussels, 1928), p. 1088. 57Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," pp. 269-270; Rapport presenté'par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société, 1928, p. 117. 58 Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," p. 270. 59Rapport presente par le Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société, 1928, p. 117. 60Annuaire Officiel du MinistEre des Colonies--de Belgique (Brussels, 1928), p. 1080; "Les Plantations de Cafe du Ruanda-Urundi," Agriculture et Elevage au Congo Bel e, Troisiéme année, no. 6 (March 23, 1929), pp. 88-89. 61CAMP. Congo Manuscripts. J. M. Derscheid Collec- tion. Territoire de Nyanza. Rapport en reponse au ques- tionnaire par 1e Gouverneur, 1929, p. 74. 62Rapport present€;par 1e Gguvernement Belge au Conseil de la Socigté, 1929, p. 71. 63 Ibid. 64CAMP. Congo Manuscripts. J. M. Derscheid Collec- tion. Territoire de Nyanza. Rapport en reponse au ques- tionnaire par le Gouverneur, 1929, p. 72. 65CAMP. Congo Manuscripts. J. M. Derscheid Collec- tion. Territoire de Nyanza. Rapport en reponse au ques— tionnaire par le Gouverneur, p. 73. 66Rapportpresente'par‘le Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société, 1924, pp. 33 and 38. 67Newbury and Higginson give the total number as 7,000 and 10,000 respectively. Higginson's source notes that in 1926, some 400 Africans were recruited from Rwanda and Burundi. However, an official report for 1926 provided the following figures: 2 July 1926, 277 recruits; 30 Au- gust 1926, 288 recruits; 16 September 1926, 231 recruits; 1 November 1926, 172 recruits; and 27 November 1926, 133 recruits, making a total of 1,101 recruits. Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," p. 416. Higginson, "The Making of an African Working Class," p. 301. 132 68Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," p. 416, and CAMP. 3e Partie: Protection du Travail. 69Higginson, "The Making of an African Working Class," p. 301. 70Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," p. 275. 71 Martelli, Leopold to Lumumba pp. 197-198. The stabilization policy was also used in the diamond fields 'of southern Kasai, in the tin and gold mines of the Kivu, and the plantations of the United Africa (Lever) Company. 72Anstey, King Leopold's Legacy, p. 119. The author also notes that the number of recruits between 1935 and 1942 was of particular significance, since the copper mines had expanded production to meet the wartime demands of the allies. 73Hailey, An African Survey, pp. 702-703. Hailey noted that despite the pronouncement the mines still employed a certain number of Africans from Rwanda and Burundi. 74 Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," pp. 275-276. 75CAMP. Rwanda. Be Partie: Protection du Travail. 76Rapport presente par le Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société, 1938, p. 76. 77Newbury, "The Cohesion of Oppression," p. 276, and Rapport presenté’par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de 78Ministere de Colonies. Ministere du Congo Belge et du Ruanda- Urundi. Rapport soumis par le Gouvernement Belge a l' Assemblie Géherale des Nations Unies au sujet de 1' Ad- ministration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant l' Anfige 1947 (Brussels, 1948), p. 61. 79Emmanuel Ruzendana, "L'Evolution du Commerce au Rwanda du dernier quart du XIXiEme a 1950" (Memoire de Licence, Louvain, 1974), p. 75. 80Almost all export activity was dominated by Euro- peans; only a few Asian firms were involved in the export trade. Most were restricted to serving as intermediaries between the European firms and Asian producers. "La Rapport sur 1' Administration Belge au Ruanda- Urundi pendant l' Annee 1923, " Congo I (January-May 1924), p. 756. - 133 81Chambres des Representants, Session de 1923-1924. Rapport sur l'Administration Belge du Ruanda-Urundi presenté au Chambres (Brussels, 1924), p. 25. 82"La Rapport sur l'Administration Belge au Ruanda- Urundi pendant l'Année 1923," Congo I, (January-May, 1924), p. 752. Chambre des Representants, Session de 1923- 24. Rapport sur l'Administration Beige du Ruanda-Urundi presente aux Chambres, p. 20. 83 p. 103. 84Rapportpresentépar 1e Gouvernement Belge, 1928, pp. 80 and 84. 85 Rapport presenté;par 1e Gouvernement Beige, 1925, Ibid., pp. 92 and 96. 86Rapportpresent'é'par le Gouvernement Belge, 1929, pp. 96 and 100. 87Alison L. Des Forges, "Defeat is the Only Bad News: Rwanda Under Musinga, 1896-1931" (Ph.D. thesis, Yale University, 1972), pp. 342-343. 88 o. 157. L Rapportpresenté'par 1e Gouvernement Belge, 1931, 89Rapportpresente'par 1e Gouvernement Belge, 1932, pp. 128 and 130. 90Ruzendana, "L'Evolution du Commerce au Rwanda," pp. 90 and 95. 91Rapport presentéipar le Gouvernement Belge, 1930, p. 6. 921bid., p. 86. 93Rapport soumis par le Gouvernement BelgeL 1949, p. 116. 94 Fred E. Wagoner, “Nation Building in Africa: A Description and Analysis of the Development of Rwanda" (Ph.D. thesis, The American University, 1968), pp. 91-92. 95Ibid., pp. 92—93. Rapport presenté’par 1e Gouverne- 96 p. 103. Rapport presente par le Gouvernement Belge, 1926, CHAPTER FOUR THE EMERGENCE OF THE IMPERIAL STATE: ECONOMIC CONSOLIDATION State intervention and the attraction of the developed sectors in eastern Zaire and in neighboring British terri- tories stimulated capital formation in Rwanda. Capital surplus was generated from African taxes and labor from the mid—1920 to 1928; state intervention in the same period increased steadily, facilitating development of civil ad- ministration and the country's infrastructure. This chap- ' ter shows, however, that with the collapse of the world economic system in 1929, the colonial state at the insis- tence of the Metropole, was left to its own devices. Transforming the country was an expensive business, and the Metropole, preoccupied with its own domestic economy and what had been the enormously profitable Belgian Congo, could no longer subsidize the Rwandan economy. The latter would have to support itself or sink. The Colonial Office at Brussels sent Charles Voisin to increase economic pro- duction and to maintain the colony's solvency. This chap- ter explores the dynamics that were involved in the Voisin administration from 1930 to 1933. 134 135 In 1928 and 1929, the world had experienced excellent harvests. In fact, there was overproduction in wheat, cof- fee, cocoa, palm oil and nuts, cotton and sugar, and sur- pluses in copper, tin, lead, and aluminum production. The markets for these products collapsed during the last quar- ter of 1929 and continued into the following year.1 The best prices for some varieties of Arabica declined from a high of BF 25 to BF 15 per kilo by the end of November 1930.2 Declining agricultural prices undermined recently established commercial enterprises in Belgian Africa. Brussels advised its colonial officials to tell companies Operating in the Congo and Rwanda to take "vigorous mea— sures" to lower the cost of their products. Consequently, companies worked to eliminate all expenditures on non- productive fixed assets and non—essential branch operations to lower costs; many also reduced European personnel and increased the duration of contractual obligations.3 Agri- cultural, mining, transportation, and commercial firms were forced to revise their accounting methods and to drop retail prices.4 Companies which were badly organized and managed, or founded on pure speculation, collapsed. Only firms which were firmly established or which agreed to the necessary fiscal sacrifices survived. Struggling companies also re- ceived government support, especially agricultural enter- prises, which were hit hardest by the depression. The 136 creation of a crisis fund and agricultural credit helped some to survive the economic decline. On March 25, 1930, the government also helped out by cancelling export duties for two years on vegetable products, palm oil, and sugar cane,5 and by increasing import duties on commodities, such as sugar, which competed with local produce. In Belgium, whereas import duties on foreign beans rose 250BF per ton for roasted coffee and 100BF per ton for unroasted varieties, coffee coming from Belgian Africa entered the metropole duty free.6 The economic crisis forced the colonial administration to make up for lost revenues. Consequently, officials in- creased receipts, taxes, and charges on producers (see Appendix IV), severely weakening the small but growing 7 As the crisis intensified, African capitalist sector. Belgian officials were also confronted with drastic re- dressments of their own, particularly in finances, econ- omic develOpment, and administrative personnel. They had over-develOped certain social services, in which either had to be reduced or their expenses passed on to African producers through increased charges.8 The economic crisis also pointed out the administra- tion's over concern with economic development rather than economic consolidation. For example, the commercial sec- tors of the Belgian Congo and Rwanda had registered severe complaints, since the mid 19203, with the administration 137 in Brussels about the high cost of transporting goods to overseas markets. According to official reports, trans- portation rates varied considerably and the disparities in rates made very little sense. For example, water trans- portation from Uvira to Kigoma on Lake Tanganika took twelve hours, but cost as much as shipping merchandise from Stanleyville to Leopoldville in nine days. Also, on the Uvira to Bukavu route, a kilometric ton was BBF, but it also cost 12BF from Kissengny to Rutshuru, a much shorter distance. The rationale for the latter was oil cost and the rapid amortization for the use of lorries which had to traverse defective roads. Rather than resolve the transportation problem, officials concentrated on ex- panding‘and formulating development projects, with result- ing overexpansion when the crisis developed. Then, crit- ics called for a reassessment of development priorities, and warned that further development in the Kivu, Rwanda and Burundi, could not be accomplished without lowering transport costs and mileage disparities.9 By 1931, the rock-bottom of the "world crisis" had been touched, but its effects were not fully felt in Rwanda until 1932, when the added instability of the monetary sit- uation and of finances in general began to paralyze local trade. In fact, commerce virtually stopped in 1931, when Africans, in response to low world prices, kept their hides off the market in the hope of an impending price 138 increase or used them to manufacture personal garments.10 Small, medium, and independent European enterprises virtu- ally disappeared, except for Greeks in the hotel trades, butchers and bakers.11 Requests for agricultural land ceased, and a number of land contracts (concessions) were 12 In 1932, one European firm and thirteen Asian cancelled. ones were adjudged bankrupt. Three of the latter were granted concordat apiés faillite, and two received pre- 13 ventive bankrupt certificates. Most farmers reduced their activities; others abandoned their enterprises alto- gether or turned to the production of food crops, instead of sisal and coffee.14 Road construction on the Bujumbura- Uvira-Cyangugu route could not be completed.15 Consequent- ly, during 1932, the number of employed Africans, other than porters, declined after road work and public projects were terminated, because the colonial government lacked the money to finance road construction.16 In 1931, the budget deficit of 5.9 million francs forced the administration to reduce expenditures by de- 17 The following year, creasing personnel and materials. custom duties were again greatly reduced, receipts declined by more than 50 percent (see Appendix IV), and officials reduced expenditures principally on salaries and allow- ances for European personnel, and material. These pro- duced a 16 percent savings for the administration,18 but could hardly stave off a possible default by the colonial 139 state. Outstanding loans owed to the Belgian Congo and the metropole were due and had to be paid. From the begin- ning of the mandate to 1929, Belgium had loaned the terri- tories of Rwanda and Burundi 28.8 million francs which was to be progressively amortized from 1926. Brussels was supposed to receive 26,407,781 francs in December 31, 1932, but because of financial problems, an agreement on October 15, 1931, converted the debt to a treasury bond. At the same time, in order to finance road construction, the territories secured a second loan of 50 million francs at a low interest rate of 2 percent annually, repaid in 1932 by converting it to a treasury bond. Both Rwanda and Burundi also possessed a floating debt, which was supported by both Belgium and the Belgian Congo. By 1932 seven million francs in bonds were held by Belgium and 96.5 million francs, including the converted treasury bond of 50 million francs were owed to the Belgian Congo.19 Despite the mandate's indebtedness or because of it, gov- ernment officials embarked on a "rationalized development plan" in order to increase foreign exchange. Governor General Voisin's primary mission was the implementation of this kind of development. When Charles Voisin was named Vice-Governor General and Governor of the Territory of Ruanda-Urundi on 28 May 1930, he announced the government's official development program in the preamble to the 1930 Annual Report. He 140 included, among other objectives: the regrouping of chief— doms for better administrative control; the improvement of livestock; reforestation; mineral prospecting; and the con— 20 In a speech before his administra-i struction of roads. tive officials in September of the same year, the governor added the following projects: a program to remedy periodic famine and the undernourishment of the Africans; the de- velopment of markets so that Africans could get cash in return for their excess production, which would in turn stimulate their purchasing power; the participation of Europeans in the economy;21 and the construction of schools.22 The first program called for swamp drainage to pro- vide new land, and the development of seasonal crops such as manioc, which is resistant to excessively dry and wet seasons, to supplement the African diet, especially during periods of famine. To develop markets required the con— struction of extensive road networks, so that lorries could replace African carriers and connect markets with commercial centers and ports. Although the goal of Euro- pean participation in agricultural production was never fully realized, Voisin's program provided land concessions in areas of "vacant lands and limited pOpulation" in order to improve the land and demonstrate proper cultivation measures for Africans. European participation, however, was more successful in the industrial and commercial 141 sectors. The land designed for European agricultural pro- duction was much too marginal and unsuitable for European settlement.23 The technical aspects of Voisin's program were refined by Mr. M. Everaerts, the newly assigned agricultural direc- tor and guiding influence for agricultural development from 1929 to 1954, but the substance of the program was not at all new. The theoretical and practical applications of much of it had been developed between 1916 and 1930, espe- cially labor recruitment, wage employment, taxation and trade in African foodstuffs (see Chapter III.) Governor Voisin's development plan of 1930 also called for reorganizing and standardizing the lines of com— municatiOn, running from the administration through the chief and sub-chief, to the rural population. It was be- lieved that only through the modification of the tradition- al structure and, correspondingly, its function, could de- 24 The velopment or the civilizing mission be initiated. vital links were the chiefs and sub-chiefs, and their role was a pivotal one, provided they could be made to acquire European values, which the administration assumed would 25 As chiefs became more increase the rate of progress. amenable to European influences or civilization, they could better assume the responsibility for communicating ideas and directives from the administration to the masses below. They would implement directives related to the 142 cultivation of crops, swamp drainage, reforestation, road construction, and tax collection. Those who were incapable of following administrative orders and decrees would be replaced, scolded, beaten, orjailed.26 Some chiefs would also have their property confiscated, or administrative officials would indiscriminately destroy the homes and crops of the chief's subjects,27 to ensure compliance and submission. However, Voisin's administrative reorganization plan was not entirely new either. A major program, begun in the 19203 had attempted to regroup African chieftaincies by amalgamating the hundreds of scattered enclaves and small holdings that had developed as a result of the tra- ditional land tenure system and ibikingi.28 The govern- ment's goal to organize the country into Chiefdoms of roughly the same size, with at least 100 taxpayers in 29 The earlier program also had extended administra- each. tive control and development projects as well as the ef- forts of African agents on the hills. At the same time, European officials increased the political power of their chiefs, particularly where authority was exercised in the public interest. Those who acted on the administration's behalf were young educated notables, with a mOre evolved mentality because of western education. These educated chiefs eventually replaced the more traditional authori- ties who the administration believed were incapable of 143 adapting their actions to new methods.30 To foster agricultural development, Voisin decided to expand cotton, palm oil, coffee and tobacco, primarily be- cause he believed high transportation costs prohibited the development of other crops.31 He believed that the selec- ted products would yield higher value, which would thus offset high transport costs.32 The rationale for expanding coffee cultivation was also based on the belief that coffee would greatly influence the general economic growth of the country, provided it was undertaken by Africans. The gen- eral costs for blacks, "who have recourse to family labor in planting, maintenance, and harvesting were quite low in comparison with those which confronted the European culti- vation efforts." Voisin and his officials also believed Africans would profit from coffee production.33 Moreover, Governor Voisin called for some modifications and more rational development in animal husbandry. Only then, he argued, would livestock occupy the preponderant place in the balance of foreign exchange. But the real problem here was supervision because much of the trade could not be documented or taxed at the border (exit) points. Ac- cording to administration estimates, at least 2,000 head of cattle exited annually from the country unnoticed, especially at points near frontier markets at Banyabongo 34 and the Bahunde of the Kivu district. This meant poten- tial revenues were being lost. 144 Another feature of the new rationalized development called for European participation in the economy, a policy which the administration had sanctioned since 1925, when it agreed to grant concessions of large tracts of land to business interests.35 To protect the normal development of the African population and to prevent monopolies by foreign colonists and other foreigners, the administration did not permit land transfers unless an equitable indem- nity was transacted,36 and the Africans agreed to abandon their rights.37 Densely populated agricultural land would not be granted if African residential patterns would be upset. Furthermore, concessions in these zones were usu- ally limited to a maximum of 500 hectares, and a second concession would be granted only after the first one was in full production. Companies or owners also had to agree to build schools and quarantine stations as part of the social contract.38 In 1928 the legislative branch approved three agree- ments which recognized the right of recipients to acquire property rights to the land. Two limited land grants could be chosen in deserted areas, generally in the prox- imity of forests, or tse-tse infected regions, where of- ficials hoped European methods could make these areas 39 . . A restrictive clause to ensure healthy and productive. development recognized the right of ownership only if the land was placed in production within a reasonable period 145 of time, and social obligations were entirely fulfilled.40 But as the table below indicates, despite what was appar- ently a very liberal land policy, there were few firms in Rwanda. Most were Indian and Arab firms which predomi- nated throughout the colonial period. Increases after 1926 reflected non-European growth, and from 1923 to 1927 Belgian firms were never the majority.41 Table VII. The Total Number of Agricultural and Com- mercial Firms in Rwanda, 1923-1929. Total Number of Total Number of Year Firms Year Firms 1923 27 1927 85 1924 29 1928 94 1925 77 1929 107 1926 71 SOURCE: "La Rapport sur l'administration Belge pendant l'année 1923," Congo I~(Jan. - May, 1924), 756; Rapport 1925, 102; Rapport 1926, 103; Rapport 1927, 79; Rapport ‘1928, 91; and Rapport‘l929, 96. To make investment in Rwanda more attractive and as a response to the problem of limited financial resources for new but floundering companies, the administration changed its concession policy in significant ways. First, it passed Ordinance No. 18 on June 28, 1929, creating a 146 system of progressive renewals for agricultural leases at intervals of five years. The ordinance aimed to assist struggling companies, which were allowed to retain their profits until their holdings were in full production.42 Second, Voisin began to promote more vigorously the con- cepts of partnership between Africans and Europeans and protective zones. Both concepts worked side-by-side. For example in areas designated as protective zones, companies which agreed to assist Africans would be assured of a monopoly for ten years. Protective zones would enclose an area of 70,000 hectares or more, in which companies would have full access to African labor and produce. By the end of 1929, twenty-one protective zones had been leased or were on the verge of being reserved.43 By permitting private enterprises to take "legiti- mate" advantage of African labor and production, as well as permitting companies to rationalizing their own capital, officials believed development would be more efficient and rational.44 To further justify their actions, the admin- istration maintained that they would profit from the cre- ation of European agricultural zones. The companies would serve as demonstration agents and would provide the Ban- yarwanda with seeds, cuttings, and selected plants. More— over, observation would lead them to unconsciously use more improved cultivation techniques.45 The concepts of partnership and protective zones were good inducements for 147 European companies; the notables secured labor for them, while various companies obtained export crops either di- rectly from Bahutu farmers or, more frequently, from Hindu and Arab agents. The latter held a near monoply in trans- acting business with Africans; they served as middlemen between EurOpean importers and African consumers, and be- tween local producers and export houses, as well as for industrial firms in regions adjacent to the Belgian Congo.46 The final components of the developmental strategy were perhaps the most important. Voisin sought to encour- age the growth of mining concessions as a means of aug— menting foreign exchange. The first concession for the exploitation of six deposits of tin was awarded to the Minetain Society in 1930. Export production for that year was 164 tons, but by 1949 the output had risen to 2,267 tons, and mineral exports would become the second ranking source of foreign exchange after coffee.47 Then, there was the problem of insufficient pasture and Rwanda's many cattle.48 The government believed that cattle should be improved by breeding Rwanda animals with European stock or with cattle from neighboring colonies. Culling herds would also result in less animals that would 49 Batutsi notables therefore require less pasture land. vigorously resisted reductions, however, and the adminis- tration never made much headway except in the area of im- proving the health of the herds. 148 To combat famine, non-seasonal crops such as manioc and sweet potatoes were introduced, and regulations im- posed for their cultivation. The resident had the power to require each able bodied adult male to maintain 35 ares of seasonal and 15 ares of non-seasonal food crops. The latter included manioc or above 1900 meters, potatoes.50 Manioc could be sown in bush land or on well drained 51 Since slopes apart from each household's land holding. the country lacked suitable storage facilities, the selec- tion of these durable crops was a wise choice, and if Bahutu farmers complied with the rules, famines would no longer disrupt the productive cycle. Voisin strongly pur- sued this program, and recalcitrants were subject to fines of fifty to a hundred francs for failure to follow instruc- tions to the letter.52 Other regulations decreed the use of bottom marsh lands for agricultural purposes, a great source of irrita- tion to the Batutsi notables, primarily because of the need for dry season pastures.53 The notables found ways to circumvent the new directive, usually through "benigned neglect" or gracious non-compliance. Finally, since land in Rwanda had been systematically depleted of its forests by agriculturalists seeking new fields, Belgian officials instituted a forest reclamation project, in which Banyar- wanda had to plant commercial groves of fast-growing trees, particularly eucalyptus, to be used as firewood and in 149 construction.54 Voisin's basic developmental goals were to improve African agricultural production in order to resist the threat of famine, to provide enough surplus for the African to purchase the things he could not grow, pay taxes and to create foreign exchange in order to maintain colonial sol- vency. Government would support these goals by building roads which would open the land; by finding markets which would purchase the Africans' surplus production; and by providing proper technical knowledge and supervision. There were, however, some enormous and fundamental prob- lems which prevented the achievement of these goals: first, population was widely dispersed in a country of precipitous slopes and denuded hillsides; second, there was the social role of cattle expressed by imperatives and taboos not only difficult to change but also deeply im- bedded in the traditional political system. If the asso- ciations of value and prestige attached to cattle could be transferred to some other object or social manifestation, then the technical solution of the problem of rational stock breeding would be easy. The third obstacle was the density and isolation of the population, which meant that there were only limited areas for expansion. The basic aim of the administration was to enable a greater number to live on the already crowded cultivated land by raising its productivity and 150 by encouraging private investment on non-productive land or reclaimed land. Officials would mount campaigns to control population growth and to stress the need for hard 55 But to teach this work to increase food production. kind of awareness was an expensive undertaking in the best of times and certainly impractical in times of depression. Moreover, given the spread of Catholicism, any discussion of birth control would be difficult. To encourage foreign investment in Rwanda was reasonable, but to expect this in the 19303 was not. A fourth obstacle was traditional land and tenure, which sustained the Batutsi oligarchy, and the administra- tion had to proceed slowly in order to avoid political in- stability or even revolution. Even when it had the oppor- tunity to completely dismantle the whole system of presta- tions in 1938, the government refused because of the need to support the power and prestige of traditional authority through the symbol of allegiance which prestations repre- 56 Officials were prepared to leave this issue un- sented. resolved for some time and looked upon suppression as a final objective. The fifth obstacle was the absence of villages, which made it almost impossible to reach peOple in order to provide technical, economic, and human ser— vices.57 Even though the governor's program encouraged the creation of open air markets, which would serve to inspire surrounding stores and eventually villages, this 151 aspect of development would take time. In the meantime schools and dispensaries would have to serve as a measure 58 The final of village life in order to reach the people. obstacle was Musinga. The implementation of economic transformation lay in the efficiency of the chain-of-command, running from the administration through the chiefs and sub-chiefs to the rural masses. The vital links were naturally the chiefs. In this regard the administration was willing to respect and reinforce the authority of the Batutsi oligarchy, but only "to the extent where its functions follow our civil- "59 This aim also meant persuading izing directives. Musinga to take his duties "seriously" and to participate "actively" in the administration of his territory. Euro- pean official and missionary personnel expressed the belief that Musinga was supposedly indifferent to those things which "did not satisfy his egoism and instincts." He was concerned only with ”keeping his peOple in a state of stag- nation and with resisting the works of civilization."60 They also believed that the roots of chaos and indifference lay in the existence of an autocratic, powerful monarchy who remained captive to the whims of a band of sycophantic courtiers.61 The crisis came to a head in 1931, with the dismissal of Musinga and the accession to the throne of his eighteen; year-old-son, Rudahigwa (hereafter Mwami Mutara). The 152 origins of the crisis, according to one version, can be traced back to 1926, when it was alleged that Musinga had attempted sodomy with sons of his notables serving at the palace at Nyanza. This incident caused a breach between Musinga and his chiefs, for which he blamed the White 62 Whether Fathers, saying they had exaggerated the facts. there is any truth to these claims is difficult to say, but what is beyond question is that Musinga's relations with the Catholic Church had never been very cordial. According to Alexis Kagame, "Musinga was bitterly Opposed to missionary enterprise, because it undermined his authority."63 Musinga openly distrusted Catholic missionaries, and he adopted an attitude of passive resistance toward the administration, an attitude which Professor Marzarotti attributed to the influence of Musinga's traditional back- ground. Consequently it was difficult for anyone to change his mental outlook. The limitations which the administra- tion had imposed upon him contributed to his hostile atti- tude and latent surliness.64 But what really incensed officials was Musinga's sys- tematic opposition to all European progress and improve- ments, his preoccupation with the past, and finally his conduct during the 1928-29 famine. Musinga had failed to support reforestation and cultivation of compulsory food crops,65 but during the famine, he tried to get the 153 government to compel his starving people to supply him with the customary food tribute. The administration naturally refused the request, but persuaded him to leave his capital to tour the kingdom and encourage the peOple to plant food crops and trees for the reforestation pro- gram. Musinga travelled "with little enthusiasm," and his entourage "exacted tribute in food and cattle from the pe0ple."66 These actions were frustrating, since the administra- tion's solution to the famine was to extend food crop cultivation in the marshy lowlands, where crops could grow even if rainfall was below normal. Officials were also thoroughly disgusted with the Batutsi notables, who tended to ignore orders to clear and plant the marshes. Notables were more concerned about the fate of their cattle which constituted their sole wealth. Since the wet lowlands offered the only certain source of pasturage during drought, Batutsi notables blocked the extension of culti- 67 The frustrated Belgians sought Musinga's vation there. help in getting the Batutsi to act. The king enthusias- tically punished any of his opponents who disObeyed the orders, but he did no more than his notables to extend 68 Faced with the task of governing the king- cultivation. dom without the cooperation of the notables, Governor Pastiaux tried conciliation and returned to the earlier policy of propping up the notables' prestige and 154 69 The governor also ordered that measures authority. which had been disrupting buhake, one of the major griev- ances of the notables, be stopped. In the future, no notable would lose his client except as punishment for 70 But the major problem was still, what misbehavior. should be done with Musinga? In September 1931, Governor General Tilkens of the Belgian Congo visited BishOp Classe in order to set the date for Musinga's deposition. He was introduced to Rudahigwa, and a week later Batutsi notables were called to Kigali ostensibly for discussion‘about the economic crisis, but really to isolate Musinga in Nyanza. He was conveniently alone when he was informed that his son would succeed him. The king, who seemed to have expected the news, cried a little and left on November 16, 1931, for exile at a special residence at Kamembe in the western part of Rwanda, and ultimately to Moba, Katanga, where he 71 died on Christmas Day in 1944. Only pg Drapeau Rouge, the Manchester Guardian, and the Queen Mother protested 72 his deposition--the last even threatened suicide. Although the new mwami displayed no more sympathy to- wards Europeans than his father, his methods were quite different. Where Musinga openly challenged missionaries and administrators, Rudahigwa had a special talent for working within the confines of the established superstruc- ture, rather than against it. Mwami Mutara had come of 155 age when European rule was already firmly established, and was better able to accommodate himself to the norms of the new system. More important, he was a product of mission schools; he shared with the new generation of educated Batutsi elite the western training and education which his father so conspicuously lacked. The deposed Musinga was never able or willing to work out a mutually satisfactory relationship with the incipient "class" of mission educated Batutsi chiefs and sub-chiefs and the resulting tension played a part in his dismissal.73 According to LeMarchand, the new generation of chiefs fully sensed the significance of the social forces that lay behind the spread of Christianity. These chiefs real- ized that the preservation of their traditional claims- ultimately depended upon their endorsement of the new creed. Musinga viewed the adoption of Christianity as nothing short of a betrayal of his authority. Christian- ity meant the desacralization of the mwami-ship, and the relegation of the office-holder to a subordinate position. Musinga's obduracies stemmed from his own unwillingness to accept any sort of limitation that would alter either the sacredness of his office or the structure of his authority. Therefore, the drastic alterations eventually wrought into the system in the name of administrative efficiency made 74 Musinga all the more suspicious of Belgian intentions. With a new mwami in place, the administration 156 completed its political reforms, or reorganization, and 75 implemented other economic reforms. For example, tra- ditional taxes in kind and in work, owed to the Batutsi 76 The notables, was replaced by an annual money payment. new tax procedure freed Africans from porterage of produce delivered in tribute and from the billeting and provision- ing of prestation workers--burdens never considered in the evaluation of African customary contributions; and permit- ted farmers to devote more time to the production of their crops. Although the government wanted to eliminate all corvees and prestations, and replace them with a flat money payment, it decided instead to regulate them in order to prevent abuse.7.7 The administration was concerned with economic devel— opment, and any potential controversy was to be avoided. This particular issue might have caused considerable insta- bility, and was perhaps the one issue that might have united the competing functions of Batutsi noblemen. The adminis- tration, as a result, took the safest course, but it inad— vertently tightened the stronghold of the Batutsi notables over Bahutu. This issue more than any other, demonstrated the relative strength of thenotables as co-rulers, and it accentuated the inconsistencies in the colonial policy, especially since modernity implied the elimination of values and constraints harmful to the develOpment process. On the whole, the period from 1928-1931 was the apex 157 of the Belgian attempt to "rationalize and standardize" lines of control, and in doing so, the sanction of the Batutsi oligarchy as arbiters of the colonial system was confirmed. The famine convinced the administration that develOpment and African survival could not be accomplished without the nobility. Nor could reforms be instituted without first considering how they would effect the court and the Batutsi notables. As arbiters of the system, the notables increased their potential for wealth in the new economy--for certain corvee and prestation they would re- ceive a money payment. Moreover, they were part of the civil service and held the dominant places in the educa- tional system which confirmed access to the Belgian admin- istration. On another level the same period foreshadowed the consolidation of the Rwandan colonial economy, and the domination of it by the state and international economic systems. The former would redirect individual African initiative in the domestic economy for the benefit of the state. The economic crisis had severely weakened the emer- ging capitalist sector, and threatened both colonial sol- vency and the colony's development. The international economy would provide foreign exchange through the pur- chase of African surplus, allowing Africans to pay taxes and purchase imported goods. With reorganization complete and the state in control of the economy, the government could facilitate the 158 expansion of coffee production. Only with well-organized, efficiently functioning productive and administrative sys- tem could colonial officials hope to encourage and profit from economic development. Passive resistance, a recal- citrant king, and Batutsi chiefs impeded consolidation, moral and social progress, and economic development or "the civilizing process." But the administration was pre- pared to implement its plans by any means, even to the extent of deposing the traditional monarch in favor of his son Charles Mutare Rudahigwa, "who was more amenable, open, and intelligent."78 Only by standardizing and regu- lating a system of dual colonialism or overrule in which the administration and the Batutsi elite coexisted side by side or on top of each other could Belgian authorities control a doubly exploitative relationship between the masses and the Batutsi. Transforming the productive and administrative system created profound social changes, and a dual system of overrule also served to contain the expec— tations and aspirations of the Batutsi oligarchy, and con- sequently the African masses, who also had the potential for disruption. While European administrators monitored the colonial system as a whole, the Batutsi oligarchy su- pervised the productive efforts of the African population. The key to the whole system, however, was effective man- agement from the top and compliance from the Batutsi who dominated the masses below. NOTES TO CHAPTER FOUR 1Georges Van Der Kerken, La Crise Economique en Afrique Belge: Situation Actuelle et Perspective d'Avenir (Brussels, 1931), p. 25. 2Ibid., p. 39. 3Ibid., p. so 4E. Du Bois, "La Politique Economique Coloniale, 1932-34," Bulletin 1' Institut des Sciences Economiques Sixiéme Anfiee, No. 2 (1935), p. 133. 5Other decrees prolonged this temporary exemption until December 31, 1935, and a decree of June 17, 1933, extended the exemption to cotton fabrics manufactured in the colony. Du Bois, "La Politique Economique Coloniale," pp. 133-34. 6In 1935, another decree levied a 300 BF per ton export duty on unroasted coffee coming into Belgian Africa and which might be reexported duty free into Belgium. An additional decree authorized the Ministry of Colonies to reduce the statistical tax collected for certain commodi- ties at the same time customs duties were collected for products entering or leaving the country. Du Bois, "La Politique Economique Coloniale," p. 134. 7Also, by 1929 the number of non-African commercial firms in the mandate territories was 261, but by the end of 1930 the total had declined to 226. Ministére de Colonies. Ministére du Congo Belge et du Ruanda-Urundi. Rapport presenté'par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Socigté'des Nations au sujet de l'Administration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant l'Année 1930 (Brussels, 1931), p. 112. 8Van Der Kerken, La Crise Economique, p. 59. 9Ibid., p. 64. 159 160 10Actually this process had begun in 1930, when pur— chases from the Belgian Congo had begun to decline. Also appreciable decreases occurred in other export commodities to the Belgian Congo--l,212 tons in 1930 compared to 1,526 tons in 1929, a decline of 20 percent. A large segment of the decline was in hides, in spite of a reduction in duty from 10 percent to 3 percent ad valorem. Rapport 1930, pp. 29 and 113. {3"Varietés," Agriculture et Elevage au Congo Belge, Cinquieme Année, No. 4 (February 21, 1931), p. 61. 12 Rapport 1931, p. 48. 13Rapport 1932, p. 29 14Ibid., p. 156. 15"Vari§tes," p. 61. 16Consortium for African Microfilm Project (hereafter CAMP). Film NO. 34. Reel I. J. M. Derschied Collection. Territoire d'Astrida. Rapport de Sortie de Charge, (1933), p. 58. 17Rapport 1931, p. 28. 18Rapport 1932, p. 250. 19Ibid. 20Gouvernement Belge. Ministere des Colonies.Rapport presenteypar le Gouvernement belge sur 1' Administration du Ruanda et de 1' Urund1, 1930 (Brussels, 1931), pp. 5- 6; a decree of 18 December 1930 established forest areas and prohibited the cutting of wood without a permit, punishable by a fine not to exceed $100.00_and one month in prison. Large forest preserves along the Congo-Nile Divide and the slopes of the volcanoes were created in 1934. Pierre Leroy, Legislation du Ruanda-Urundi (Usumbura, 1949), pp. 61- 63. 21Fred E. Wagoner. "Nation Building in Africa: A Description and Analysis of the Deve10pment of Rwanda," (Ph.D. thesis, The American University, 1968), pp. 78-81. 22Rapportpresente’par le Gouvernement beige, 1930, p. 5. 23Wagoner, "Nation Building in Africa," pp. 82—87. 24 Alison L. Des Forges. "Defeat is the Only Bad News: Rwanda under Musinga, 1896-1931," (Ph.D. thesis, Yale University, 1972), p. 237. 161 25Rapport sur l'Administration belge du Ruanda et l'Urundi, 1923. (Brussels, 1924), p. 71. 26 Rapport presente par le Gouvernement belge, 1930, O. 5. 1. 27Des Forge, "Defeat is the Only Bad News," p. 263. 28 p. 46. 29Historique et Chronologie du Rwanda also notes that the figure would later be raised to 300 taxpayers, p. 25. 30 p. 46. 31Tobacco production was already well established in Kigali, Nyanza, Gatsibu, and Ruhengeri. Also there was a flourishing domestic trade. Buyers purchased 281,350 tobacco leafs from African farmers in Mulera, and at Kisenyi the Kamembe mill purchased 281,000 tobacco leafs. Religious missions at Rwaza and Njundo bought 600,000 and 204,000 tobacco leafs respectively in 1926. Small traders purchased more than one million tobacco leafs from African farmers. In 1929, Kisenyi and Mulera produced 200 tons. Although the industry lacked sufficient market outlets from 1934 to 1937 and production consequently declined in certain areas, tobacco production remained constant through— out 1938. Even today, it is a small but viable industry. As a result of the administration's cotton campaign, 1,900 hectares were in production by 1932. Though plagued by repeated attacks from grasshoppers (which destroyed more than 100 hectares) and plant damage caused by the rose worm (ygp rose) and other parasites, 856 tons were pro- duced in 1932. Planters averaged 90 kilos per hectare. By 1937, 724 tons of cotton was produced on 4,250 hectares. Although the 1936-37 cotton season had been a particularly good one because of adequate rainfall, cotton was still plagued by cryptagamical attacks and damaged by insects and parasites. Also, planters received only 1.10BF per kilo at government supervised markets. These 12,440 African cotton farmers produced on the average 219 kilos and received approximately 240BF for their efforts. The major cotton region was Bugarama in Cyangugu territory, producing 253,000 kilos in 1937 and 335,570 kilos in 1938. But because of low prices, planters received one franc per kilo at markets supervised by the administra- tion. By the end of 1938, there were also two ginning mills in the mandated territories. Rapport 1926, pp. 94 and 99; Rapport 1929, p. 91; Rapport 1934, p. 132; Rapport presentexpar 1e Gouvernement belge, 1929, Rapport presente par le Gouvernement belge, 1929, 162 Rapport 1937, p. 141; and Rapport 1938, p. 149 for tobacco and Rapport 1932, p. 112; Rapport 1937, p. 139; Rapport 1938, pp. 76, 147, 149, and 200 for cotton. 32 Rapport 1930, p. 106. 33Ibid., p. 114. 341hid. 35Rapport 1925, p. 79. 36In 1929, the government added the following provi- sions to its concession policy: the official survey report had to show that the land was unoccupied and would not be needed by Africans in the future. These reports were supposed to be thoroughly scrutinized by the resi- dent, and then by the governor who had the final appro- val. Rapport 1929, p. 38. 37Rapport 1926, p. 145. However, the 1929 Report noted that alienations were exceptional. In principal, administrative officials only consented to long term leases for 30 years, following a provisional contract of occupa- tion for a period of five years during which half the land should have been placed in production. Rapport 1927, p. 31 and Rapport 1929, p. 38. 38 Rapport 1927, p. 31. 39Rapport 1929, p. 38. 4OIbid. 41"La Rapport sur l'Administration Belge pendant l'Année 1923," Congo I (Jan.-May, 1924), p. 756; Rapport 1924, p. 38; Rapport 1925, p. 102; Rapport 1926, p. 103; Rapport 1927, p. 79; Rapport 1928, p. 91; and Rapport 1929, p. 96. 42Rapport 1929, p. 88. 43In 1930, the total number of European and Asian agricultural enterprises in Rwanda had been reduced to 15. The total area in full production was only 5,745 hectares and 50 ares. But Europeans and Asians held much more land in the following categories: 14,782 hectares 75 ares 58 cent'ares were devoted to private ownership; 11,881 hec- tares 75 ares were on lease arrangements; 2,843 hectares on long term lease arrangements; and 1,948 hectares in the hands of missions. About 73.4 percent of the European and 163 Asian land was in fallow: 4.18 percent in food crops; 6.20 percent in coffee; 14.7 percent in forestry; and 1.3 percent in fruit trees. Société Coloniale des Produit tannant et Agricole (Protanag), perhaps the largest com- pany in Rwanda had 1,115 hectares in production in Cyangugu in 1930. About 350 hectares of it was in coffee. Protanag used specialized technical personnel and equip- ment, such as tractors and adaptable ploughs. However, the company did not survive the economic crisis and col- lapsed in 1934, despite its efforts to liquidate some of its less profitable assets. Other European companies were located in the following areas: five in Gatsibu; three in Kigali; one in Cyangugu; two in Lubengera; and two in Ruhengeri. Most of these enterprises cultivated food crops and coffee. Rapport 1929, p. 39; Rapport 1930, pp. 112, and 149-150; and Rapport 1934, p. 87. 44 Rapport l929, p. 39. 45The administration also envisaged the eventual creation of individual land tenure systems among the Ban- yarwanda, but this was way off in the remote distant future. Ibid. 46Rapport 1930, p. 112. 47£pig., pp. 149 and 336; Wagoner, "Nation Building in Africa," p. 83. 48Over-grazing and an excessive cattle pOpulation remains a severe problem for Rwanda. Even in 1933 there were some 80,000 head of cattle, which at a rate of at least 2.5 hectares per head of cattle, required some 300,000 hectares for adequate grazing. However, the total area of the country is just 265 hectares and only 243,151 hectare were suitable for agriculture and animal husbandry. With 60,000 adult farmers cultivating 68,763 hectares, there was not sufficient land for pasture, unless yields on pasture lands could be increased. So the concern shown by the administration was a real one. CAMP. Film No. 34 Reel I. J. M. Derschied. Territoire d'Astrida. Rapport de Sortie de Change (1933), p. 59. 49CAMP. Congo Manuscript. J. M. Derscheid Collec— tion. Rapport en réponse au questionnaire par le Gouver- neur, 1929, p. 44. 50A. Becquet, "Moyens mis en Oeuvre et les Results Obtenus dans le Lutte contre la Famine au Ruanda," Journées d'Agronomie Coloniale, (June 23-24, 1933), p. 4. 164 1Pierre Bettez Gravel, "A Play for Power. Descrip- tion of a Community in Eastern Rwanda: (Ph.D. thesis, University of Michigan, 1962), p. 68. 52Ian Linden, Church and Revolution, p. 206. 53Gravel, "A Play for Power," p. 82 541hid., pp. 73-74. 55Wagoner, "Nation Building in Africa," p. 83. 56Rapport 1938, p. 75. 57Wagoner, "Nation Building in Africa," p. 185. 58Ibid. 59Rapport 1930, p. 5. 60Ibid., p. 60. 61Rene LeMarchand, Rwanda and Burundi, (London, 1970), p. 70. 62 Louis de Lacger, Rwanda (Kabgayi, n.d.), pp. 531— 538. 63Alexis Kagame, Yuhi Musinga: pp Regne mouvemente (Unpublished M.S.). 64 p. 66. 65Rapport 1929, 48. Congo Manuscript. "Folder No. 9. "Silhouette: M. Georges Sandrart." Alison L. Des Forges. "Defeat is the Only Bad News," p. 343. 66 Permanent Mandates Commission, 16th session (1929), Rapport 1929, pp. 48-49. 67Des Forges, "Defeat is the Only Bad News," pp. 343- 344. 68Ibid., p. 344. 69Ibid., p. 346. 7°Ibid., pp. 346—7. 165 71Rapport 1931, pp. 242-243; Wagoner, Nation Building in Africa, p. 95. 72 Rapport 1931, p. 247. 73LeMarchand, Rwanda and Burundi, p. 70. 74Ibid. 75In 1938, officials remarked that the mwami's role was collaborative, and in this capacity he would make periodic tours of his kingdom and report on the results to the Resident. Rapport 1938, p. 13. 76 Rapport 1931, p. 87. 77;pi9., and Rapport 1934, p. 70. 78Rapport 1931, p. 58. CHAPTER FIVE THE RWANDAN COLONIAL ECONOMY: COFFEE PRODUCTION, 1920-1937 The famine of 1928-29 in Rwanda and the Great Depres- sion of the 19303 were bench marks in the economic and colonial history of Rwanda. Both were instrumental in introducing into the country a strict system of economic planning which guaranteed the maximum productivity from the African pOpulation. Increased productivity was nec- essary in order to counter future famines, the drastic re- duction in investments, and the sharp decline in the prices of raw materials and agricultural commodities on the world market. Economic dislocation not only threatened the sol- vency of the colonial economy but could have also led to political upheaval and instability. The famine, the de- pression, and the fear of economic stagnation and politic- al instability led to a policy that Africans must carry on farming at all costs in order to maintain the economic ac- tivity and development of the colony. This policy found legal pronouncement in the late 19203 and legal enforce- ment in the 19303, when the government instituted compul- sory cultivation of export crops. Even though the decline 166 167 in agricultural export prices could have been balanced by a sharp increase in the volume of exports, the administra- tion believed, and perhaps correctly 30, that this increase would only have been achieved by reinforcing economic con- straints. The administration accomplished this end, how— ever, by enforcing strict divisions of labor between Afri- can producers and foreign capital. As this chapter shows, African producers were restricted to the production of pro- duce, at prices fixed by the administration, whereas for- eign interests obtained an effective monopoly over the industrial processing of these products and thus were able to profit from the added value. The history of Rwandan coffee production falls into three phases. The first, from 1920 to 1931, includes the formative years which were characterized by opposition from the Batutsi oligarchy. The second, 1931 to 1937, com- prises the administration's successes with the introduction and extension of the product throughout Rwanda. The final phase, although not clearly delineated, ends in 1939, when the industry collapsed from events neither Rwandans nor the colonial administration could control. This chapter will explore only the first two phases. Because the final phase involved events external to Rwanda, it will be discussed in Chapter Seven. When Voisin decided to extend coffee cultivation in 1931, feasibility studies nor the creation of new technical 168 facilities were required, because as early as 1920, coffee nurseries had been constructed by the government, and in 1921, 1000 coffee plants were distributed to African farm- ers. In 1923, officials made every effort to extend cof- fee growing in the African areas, and they predicted that the first harvest by Bahutu chiefs would be sold in 1924.1 This forecast demonstrated how little officials knew about coffee, since it takes several years for young trees to bear fruit. With extreme optimism, they proceeded to con- struct nurseries, to train African monitors, and to dis- tribute coffee plants (about 100,000) in 1923.2 In 1924, however, drought severely damaged the coffee nurseries created in 1923, and only a tenth of the plants distrib- uted to Africans were able to develop.3 Undaunted by this initial setback, the administration purchased 500 kilos of seed to establish new nurseries in each of the residences. It also obtained 12,000 new plants from the Catholic mission at Mibirizi, which were planted in the territory of cyangugu.4 In 1924, the government distributed 100,000 young plants, the Catholic missions about 30,000, and several administrative posts lesser quan- tities. Guatemala, Bourbon, and Robusta were varieties given to African farmers,5 but the administration ulti- mately decided to concentrate on Arabica, since it was considered superior to the other species. Furthermore, it was quite sturdy, and thus able to withstand harsh 169 weather conditions.6 Total coffee production for both territories was 22 tons in 1924. In 1925, in a policy shift, Belgian agricultural offi- cials compelled Batutsi chiefs and notables to provide additional land to Bahutu farmers, and they intensified the coffee campaign.7 However, the former measure enactment did not result in increased production, primarily because there was resistance from some Bahutu who considered the produc- tion of coffee as having no immediate contribution to their daily food requirements, and from Batutsi, who failed to implement the instructions, because he believed coffee cul- tivation was a threat to their power.8 In 1926, Territorial agents, either at their own ini- tiative, or with the assistance of Batutsi chiefs, estab- lished several nurseries in the provinces of Kihunya, Ba- ganza, Mirenge, and Bumbogo. Officials hoped eventually to distribute coffee plants to Bahutu farmers who had be- come proprietors of their own land. .Similar efforts had produced successful results in cyangugu territory, where a census revealed that Africans had 30,000 productive cof- fee plants. Officials were also pleased that the program instituted in cyangugu had occurred without the use of force.9 Success in Cyangugu generally and in the mandate specifically encouraged the administration to extend coffee growing to the warmer parts of the country in lower alti- tude zones.10 170 The mandate produced only ten tons of coffee in 1927, since extremely dry weather conditions and hail had severe— ly damaged coffee trees. Still a large number of nurseries were established around administrative posts, missions, and 11 Nor did the disaster dis- on the hills during the year. rupt agricultural development plans. Although the admin- istration closed some agricultural facilities, like the experimental agricultural station at Lusungu (closed on February 25, 1927),12 officials also began to centralize newer stations and expand the functions of existing ones. A new station, located between Nyanza and Butare in southern Rwanda, was opened at Rubona. Among its many functions was the responsibility of introducing cash and 13 After the closing of the Karuzi station new food crops. in 1935, the administration concentrated all of its efforts at the Rubona station. While the Kisozi station in north- ern Rwanda was still charged with the selection of wheat, coffee and food plants, specifically suited for the areas of high altitude, the Rubona station was responsible for devising, on a much larger scale, experiments on coffee and on food crops like manioc and sweet potatoes, and with determining whether these crops could be introduced in temperate zones. Rubona also conducted experiments in soil regeneration and in improving the breed of cattle.14 Although Rubona assumed some responsibility for training African monitors after 1930, in 1927 the Kitega station 171 in Burundi trained African agricultural personnel as moni- tors for crops, forestry, and animal husbandry.15 In 1928 and 1929, African planters at Butare and Kigali received 15BF per kilo for their coffee. By the end of November 1930, the best varieties of Arabica commanded 16 The relative decline in coffee only 10BF per kilo. prices coincided with the increasing pessimism of some Bel- gian officials about the future of coffee in the African area. They complained that little progress had been made since 1927, which they attributed to the African complaints that coffee competed with their food production and re- quired too much care.17 But others, however, were undaunt- ed, and voiced the belief that coffee would one day become a great source of wealth, provided it received government support in terms of technical and scientific assistance, easy transport terms, and limited fiscal and social ex- penses. They called for more frequent visits to African farms by members of the Agricultural Service, so that the people could be instructed in the proper care of coffee plants. These officials believed that European expertise would improve the yield of agriculture considerably. To teach African farmers what European called methods of rational cultivation--1and and seed selection, sowing in rows and alternate sowing, the proper use and arrange- ment of compost, irrigation and drainage--agricultural 18 agents were placed in each territory. These officials 172 concluded that the lack of progress in African agriculture had more to do with adequate care rather than any African attitude. They cited as evidence the stunted growth and high mortality rate of coffee plants after the first harvest.19 They were also convinced that coffee growing could be profitable despite declining prices. Moreover, the coffee was the principle way of loosening the hold of the traditional political authorities and pastoral and land patrons. At the same time profits from coffee would not only increase the purchasing power of the inhabitants, but it would also have beneficial effects on all commerce, both domestic and foreign.20 By 1930 there was further evidence to suggest that coffee could be profitable. During the late 19203, the world market prices of 20 francs per kilo had encouraged Belgian speculators to invest heavily in Arabica coffee plantations in the Kivu and Ituri. It was then believed that the Kivu could become another Kenya: excellent cli- mate, the condition of the land, and the relative ease in which cheap labor could be recruited were causes for that kind of optimism. Even when the coffee market collapsed several years later, Belgian investors still believed that the price per kilo would eventually reach the pre-war level of llBF, so companies in the Kivu continued to in- 21 crease coffee acreage. Similar optimism prevailed with respect to the future of coffee cultivation in Burundi. 173 Albert Gille, commenting on the participation of Africans in coffee production, noted that demographic and political and psychological factors were ideal and would remain so, as long as the reforms in the traditional political struc- ture were moderated and Europeans supervised all phases of coffee production.22 Commercial agriculture, though small in volume, was dominated by Europeans. African production was insignifi- cant, but the administration in Rwanda hoped that both sec- tors would expand, and was excited when several private groups proposed to finance the extension of African culti- vation. Under their plan, technical assistance, coffee seedlings, and tobacco plants would be provided. They had apparently even secured financial assistance from Belgian financiers to back the venture. But the plan collapsed because Brussels believed the proposal was contrary to the United Nations mandate prohibiting privileged commercial concessions. There were, however, other explanations: while the Belgian Foreign Office had already decided to sponsor African commercial agriculture, the colonial appa- ratus was not yet ready to assume this responsibility, for the reorganization of the administrative structure was still in progress. Also, officials needed time to prepare- for Batutsi Opposition, which had surfaced in 1927 when 23 Governor Marzorati sought to increase coffee cultivation. Administrative officials were convinced that the 174 Batutsi notables would resist any encroachment on their grazing lands, just as the Batutsi believed, with good reason, that Belgian colonialism would lessen their influ- ence and power. In 1925, the administration consolidated the authority of notables through the creation of African tribunals. More importantly and even more threateningly, Belgian authorities prohibited the collection of certain dues in kind and reduced prestations or corvee labor, of- ficially to one day out of seven or fifty-two days per year.24 In 1926, officials abolished three hierarchical ranks, which, until then, had retained with them certain powers of command which cut across those of the Chieftains of the various hills. These ranks had also called for dues on the part of producers to be given to the men who 25 The Batutsi saw Marzorati's efforts held the positions. favoring commercial agriculture as an additional encroach- ment on their prerogative and political influence, although they did not understand that these actions presaged the dismantling of the tributary mode of production. Although the administration could anticipate the Tutsi elite's reaction to the introduction of cash crops, they were surprised by the response of Bahutu planters, who re- fused to add an alien crop to their traditional subsistence pattern. They understood what the administration did not grasp; land was in short supply because of population pres- sures and soil infertility. More significant were the 175 limited size of family holdings, the large number of cattle, and the specter of frequent famines. But the ad- ministration was confident that the crop was suitable for Rwanda, and for this reason "felt coffee would one day be- come a great source of wealth."26 However, for the sake of caution, the cultivation program, initiated by Voisin in 1931, was extended in stages, not only to avoid risks that were inevitably involved in a much greater dispersal effort but to also give the administration time to mobil- ize its cadre. Moreover, the program was first initiated by chiefs and literate Batutsi, and would be introduced gradually among the Bahutu as African monitors were created to instruct them. Officials also promised to subject cof- fee to rigorous health standards, and African fields would be supervised by a specialized staff, who would determine the best land to use in order to prevent depreciation of the product. They would classify coffee into categories and mill and process it by modern techniques.27 In spite of insufficient technical personnel, Voisin's initial trials were quite satisfactory.28 During the 1931- 1932 coffee campaign, the administration followed proced- ures used in other parts of East Africa, particularly the clean-weeding process, the use of notables as demonstration 29 To dis- agents and model fields of 250 to 1,000 plants. tribute seedlings and to facilitate the 1931 coffee cam- paign, thirty agronomists and agricultural agents, with 176 the encouragement of the governor, supervised the creation of nurseries, planted seedlings, and began to monitor plantations.30 Free seedlings were distributed and the Agriculture Service supplied demonstrations on mulching techniques, not easy tasks when you consider that thirty agricultural personnel were responsible for both terri- tories, and thousands of African novices were being en- couraged to participate in the campaign. To augument its own efforts, the government also relied upon the nurs- eries of private companies that had adopted the principle 31 To avoid encroaching upon cultivated of collaboration. lands, officials chose to plant coffee on virgin lands and on poor pasture areas. In November 1931, additional cof- fee seedlings were distributed, and by the end of the rainy season, 448,300 plants were cultivated by African farmers. By the end of December of the following year, Rwandan farmers under administrative supervision, had planted an additional 309,850 coffee plants.32 Because notables were indifferent and neglected their coffee cr0ps, initial results were mediocre. There were also logistical, technical, and environmental problems that had to be overcome, especially when fields were located on denuded ridges far away from the notable's homestead. Nat- urally the failure rate was fairly high,33 and of the more than 764,000 coffee plants cultivated by December 1932, only 465,000 plants survived. Losses were attributed to 177 several factors other than exposure. First, thousands of Africans were encouraged to plant without ever having prac- ticed the cultivation of coffee or without having received the promised professional instruction. Consequently, many plants etiolated immediately after planting. Second, oth- ers were attacked by parasites--yg£4g£i§ and mole crickets-- 34 which caused a great deal of damage. Severely weakened plants were destroyed, and several fields had to be aban- 35 Decaying plants were replaced, while doned entirely. surviving ones were given extreme care. Many were trans- planted to an artificial environment and intercalated with albizzatephrosia plants, banana trees, and other leguminous plants to provide shade. Officials instituted terracing on very high slopes and the mulching of coffee fields during the dry season.36 From this point on, many believed coffee planting 37 Government officials would have satisfactory results. were buoyed by the spill over effect of the campaign, for the total amount of coffee exported from the mandate in 1931 was 65,147 kilos, and the foreign exchange earned from exports amounted to 322,296BF.38 Some European planters were more realistic, since they recognized that it would take from six to twelve years before the surviving plants 39 The following year would have serious possibilities. Rwanda produced 70 tons of coffee, and when the 1933 cam- paign began, about 1,500,000 coffee plants were cultivated 178 in the first quarter of the year throughout the mandate.40 Generally these plants were cultivated on the versant of hills or wantonly on slopes, the only available land. Some terracing was arranged to retain rain water and to prevent deep channeling and erosion.41 During the 1932-1933 campaign, the administration ex- tended coffee cultivation to the Bahutu farmers. To ensure success the administration sought to simplify planting pro- cedures, and African initiative was severely circumscribed. Monitors, assisted by a European, selected and demarcated fields and staked out the holes for plants. The extreme supervision was a formidable task, for agents travelled from hill to hill to demonstrate the proper planting tech- 42 The territorial agents would nique and provide counsel. also participate in a monthly meeting with the Batutsi chiefs and sub-chiefs, to discuss food crOps and the prog- ress of the coffee campaign and reforestation, prestations and taxes, and new policy pronouncements, regulations and ordinances. During these meetings, African tax collectors were required to verify their accounts, and individual cases were heard and judged.43 To facilitate supervision over geographical areas, agricultural personnel grouped individual parcels into tens or hundreds. Instead of concentrating nurseries in the principal urban centers, the Agriculture Service con- structed and distributed nurseries throughout the various 179 provinces. Generally these nurseries serviced some small-scale enterprises to develop, and it provided alternative earning opportunities for some farmers, particu- larly evident in Kinyaga or western Rwanda. They grew crops to supplement subsistence income. While this kind of activ- ity has potential, it has not as yet generated a full-time alternative occupation for African agriculturalists generaflyu 344 However, it provided and continues to provide security against bad harvests, and to a limited extent it generates some surplus for a few Rwandans in Kinyaga. For the majority of Rwandans, the state's agricultural economy created impotence, inequality, and indifference. The traditional elite, as a result of transformation or change brought about by the colonial state, lost status (i.e. sover— eignty) but gained powers at the expense of the population at large. Bututsi siphoned labor and agricultural surplus from below and consequently accentuated class divisions and dis— tinctions. The majority, with little or no control over the means of production, exercised little interest in the state's develOpment plans, since planning did not facilitate the pro- vision of social and productive services and economic infra- structure or afford greater and more diversified consumption for them. Nor should the state have received their support, since no attempt was made to know their needs as the major- ity perceived them. Instead the state's economic plan con- doned commodity production, and in doing so, almost threat- 35 Even those services that the adminis- ened subsistence. tration committed to Africans were either so technocratic or demeaning (in terms of abuse) that the peasantry's appre- ciation or awareness of the efforts being made by the state were undermined. No social contract existed between the state and the African masses; consequently the development process had little meaning or relevance for them. NOTES TO CHAPTER EIGHT 1Rapport presente’par 1e Govnernement Belge au Conseil de la Société des Nations au sujet de 1' Administration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant l' Annee 1932 (Brussels, 1933), p. 103. William A. Hance and Irene S. von Dangen, "Matadi, Focus of Belgian African Transport," Annals of the Associ- ation gf_American Geographers (March, 1958), pp. 41-42, 50, 56 and 57. The authors note that between 1906 and 1928 the southeastern portion of the Congo used ports of Beira and Mozambique and the Union of South Africa. To induce Congo trade to flow via Matadi, two special systems of com- modity and through-rates were adopted in 1932. The pull of the Lobito route, opened in 1932, and to a lesser extent of Beira on the mineral traffic area remained very strong. 2Chambres des Representants. Session de 1923-24. Rapport sur 1' Administration Belge du Ruanda-Urundi pre- senté aux Chambres (Brussels, 1924), p. 18. Rapport 1925, p. 89. Rapport 1927, p. 67. 3Rapport 1925, p. 103. 4Rapport 1932, p. 103. 5 Rapport 1937, pp. 160-161; Rapport 1938, pp. 170-171. 6Rapport 1926, p. 103. 7Rapport 1937, p. 131. The figure of 3,995 tons does not include imports designated for the Belgian Congo. 8Rapport 1930, pp. 29 and 120. 9 Rapport 1937, p. 132 and Rapport 1938, p. 242. 10"Rapport sur 1' Administration Belge du Ruanda-Urundi pendant l' Annee 1934," Congo, II (June-December, 1935), p. 767. i 11 Hance and Dangen, "Matadi," pp. 61-63. 345 346 12Rapport 1927, pp. 81-102. The list of imported items and countries are fairly consistent, except in the late 19308 when Japan, Tanganyika, the United States, Britain and Uganda became major importing nations after the metropole. See the following annual reports: Rapport 1928, pp. 93-116; Rapport 1929, pp. 97-122; Rapport 1930, pp. 123-148; Rapport 1933, pp. 162-191; Rapport 1934, pp. 148-179; Rapport 1935, pp. 147-180; Rapport 1936, pp. 153-186; Rapport 1937, pp.158 -189; and Rapport 1938, pp. 168-199. 13Rapport 1927, p. 9. 14Rapport 1929, p. 96. 15Rapport 1930, p. 113. lGIbid. 17"Territoire sous Mandat," Congo I (January-May, 1937): p. 190. 18 Rapport 1924, p. 38; Rapport 1925, p. 11; Rapport 1926, p. 103; Rapport 1927, p. 79; Rapport 1928, p. 91; Rapport 1929, p. 96; Rapport 1930, p. 112; "Rapport sur 1' Administration Belge du Ruanda-Urundi pendant 1' Annee 1934," Congo, II (1935), p. 773. 19"Territoire sous Mandat," Congo I (January-May, 1938), p. 229. 20 Rapport 1938, p. 200. 21Rapport 1932, p. 156. 221bid., p. 3. 23Archives Africaines, Brussels, MinistEre des Colo— nies. Carton Agri (342), Dossier Café'C/ll: R6glementa- tion; C/II/4, d'Union des Producteur au MinistEre des Colonies, pp. 1-2. Brussels, February 9, 1945. 24Ibid., p. 2. 25Ibid. The Office du Café'Arabica in Rwanda was re- constituted in 1946 as the Office du Caf6 Indidéne du Ruanda-Urundi, but not without complaint. Two commercial houses in Rwanda, Genex and Old East charged that OCIRU was a violation of commercial freedom. But the actual issue involved was their commercial activities, which the two houses feared would be eliminated under OCIRU. See Carton Agri (342), d'Ordre des Pieces No. B/I/23-OCIRU. Note Pour 347 M. 1e Gouverneur General, Office du Cafe IndigEne du Ruanda-Urundi et Liberté Commerciale, du President O.P.A., G. Sladden, Leopoldville, January 9, 1946; and No. B/I/28, du MinistEre des Colonies, S'Eme Direction Géhérale, 1e Directeur General, Note Pour M. 1e Ministre. Brussels, February 28, 1946. 26Carton Agri (343), Dossier Café C/II; Réglementa- tion; C/II/4, p. 4. United Nations Visiting Mission to East Africa. Report on Ruanda-Urundi, 4th Session. Sup- plement No. 2, 1950, p. 24. In 1950 the supervisory com- mission of O.C.I.R.U. in Rwanda and Burundi consisted of three administrative officials, two Africans, who repre- sented the interests of planters, and four individuals chosen for their "competence." The latter represented the coffee manufacturers and exporters. 27George E. Sladden and L. Michel, "Methodes de Com- mercialisation du Caf6 Arabica produit par les Indigene du Ruanda-Urundi,9 Numero Spécial du Bulletin Agricole du Congo Belge, XLIII (1952), pp. 63-64. 28Carton Agri (342), Dossier Caf6 C/II: Réglementa— 29A. Becquet, "L'Organisation du Service de l'Agricul- ture au Congo Belge," _griculture et Elevage au Congo Belge, XXX, No. 7 (July, 1939), p. 98. 30 Ibid 0 31The minimum price was calculated from the selling prices on foreign coffee markets and took into consideration expenses incurred, factory output and a normal gross profit for the exporter. As Table III below demonstrates, these prices were constantly revised. U. N. Visiting Mission to East Africa. Report on Ruanda-Urundi. 4th Session, Sup- plement No. 2, (1950), p. 24. —-7""“r""—- 348 Table XVI. Minimum Purchasing Prices for Arabica Coffee pp parche for Rwanda and Burundi (in Belgian francs). Ordinance Ordinance No. 17/A.E., No. 23/A.E., April 7, 1941 April 21, 1943 Kisenyi, Kibuye 2.35 4.15 and Bugarama Buture, Nyanza, 2.10 3.80 Ruhengeri and Kabaya Gitarama 2.00 3.70 Kigali 1.80 3.45 SOURCE: Archives Africaines, Brussels. Ministere des Colonies. Carton Agri (342), Dossier Cafe C/ll: Reglementation; C/11/4, d'Union des Producteurs de Cafe du Congo Belge a M. Staner. Directeur au Ministere des Colonies, p. 6. Brussels, February 9, 1945. og- 349 32Carton Agri (342), Dossier Cafe C/II: Reglementa- tion; C/II/4, p. 6. 33Ibid. 34Jimmye S. Hillman, "The Role of Export Cropping in Less Developed Countries," Journal of Agricultural Eco— nomics, LCIII, No. 2. (May, 1981), p. 376. 35According to Bryceson, an emphasis on subsistence production offers very little revenue for state accumula- tion. So the state's decision to compel Africans to plant specific food crops, as an anti-famine measure, must have been done with some reluctance. Deborah Fahy Bryceson, "Peasant Commodity Production in Past-Colonial Tanzania," African Affairs, Vol. 81, No. 325 (October 1982), pp. 558- 559. CONCLUS ION When Europeans finally entered Rwanda in 1894, they reportedly found a highly centralized feudal state with rigid class differentiation between the Batutsi aristocracy, the subjugated Bahutu, and the pariah Batwa. In 1907, the Germans established their government, but until 1916 they accomplished little beyond building a small number of administrative centers and inter-connecting roads. The Germans followed the principle of indirect administration, which was continued by the Belgians when they were assigned administrative control by the League of Nations. In the 19203, with the introduction of a full-scale colonial government, the period of effective contact with Europeans, and the transformation of the country, began. Once the Belgians assumed control of the mandate, their policy had two clearly linked aims: the economic development of the colony and the welfare of the African population. Both of these aims were largely fulfilled in the sense intended by the administration, that is to say that a profitable crop like coffee was widely cultivated throughout Rwanda, and many paternalistic social programs were undertaken. These successes, however, did little to equip Rwandans with the skills and infrastructure needed to 350 351 initiate, sustain, or expand economic growth, or to permit Rwandans to feed themselves, sell their surplus, create savings and purchasing power, construct schools to educate their children, or to form institutions and agencies for effective government. Consequently, since independence in 1962, Rwanda has been wracked by intermittent stagnation or even prolonged economic regression. The compulsory nature of the colonial economic structure and the corresponding indirect participation by Africans in commercial agriculture was partially responsible for this situation. Moreover, Belgian officials were not able to carry out the goals that they had set for themselves. Initially, the administration based its policy upon two basic premises: first, that the African's basic needs were economic and, second, that a vigorous national economy would stabilize society. To accomplish these objectives, they believed that Rwanda, which was historically and geo- graphically isolated, had to be brought into the modern world. But the link-up could not be done without stabilizing the traditional political structure. Since the Batutsi oligarchy was in place, European officials, after reshaping its structure, believed they could rely upon Batutsi administration to oversee the masses. They hoped that as the "civilizing process" took hold, abuses would be curtailed; and that other reforms such as hierarchical I I ’ I command structure, reductions in corvee and prestations due-.hw . 352 would lead to the dismemberment of the traditional mode of production or the feudal system, in which Batutsi controlled the allocation of labor and land. These were realistic expectations and reforms, but very little came of them, primarily because of the administration's failure to follow through. 'Failure to eliminate the feudal system retarded capitalist development, and subsequently the emergence of a free wage labor system divorced entirely from agricultural production. The reforms of April 1917, establishing a hierarchical command system and attempts to decentralize administration at the local level were modified because the Batutsi oli- garchy refused to cooperate with an obvious attempt on the part of officials to lessen their power and control. When Musinga and his notables threatened rebellion, Malfeyt was forced to restore the former German residency system, which left the Batutsi as mediators and arbitors between the administration and the masses below. Similarly, attempts to reduce corvee and prestations failed because of the half-hearted measures and weaknesses of the administration. The official approach was gradually to replace tribute payments in kind with money payments from the taxable surplus from African production, rather than wipe the slate clean and deal immediately with Batutsi opposition to change. The piece—meal approach gave the oligarchy time to undernine the administration's efforts through intimidation, threat and non-compliance. The ‘4 ' 353 Batutsi understood thoroughly that, money payment notwith- standing, as more demands were placed upon their system and on the Bahutu, their position of privilege and prestige would be reduced. Therefore, the oligarchy fought to retain their power as the administration worked to develop the land. The competing and dissimilar goals of the Batutsi and the Belgians made the traditional society unstable and set the stage for a major confrontation between the colonizer and the oligarchy. By 1928 the mandate was in total disarray. The intrigues of Musinga and his royal court had brought the administration's development plans to a halt. The famine which occurred that same year decimated the countryside. These events made it more apparent that the administration would have to compromise with the notables. Famine relief could not be accomplished without their aid, nor, for that matter, could economic development. Tranquility was paramount, if Rwandans were to become effective producers. The administration thus assured the young notables that changes in the traditional system would be moderated and that the Bahutu would be left in their charge, except in matters pertaining to colonial development projects. Still this was not enough; there was the problem of what to do with Musinga and the old guard. First of all, the Belgians set about replacing many of the recalcitrant chiefs and, in 1930, moved against Musinga, who had grown weak because of the defection of his young 354 notables, the disarray among his more traditional supporters, who were being removed by the administration, and his own isolation stemming from his inability to accomodate Catholic missionaries and Catholicism. With the deposition of Musinga, the administration accelerated its reorganization program, extended compulsory cultivation throughout Rwanda, announced a propaganda campaign for coffee cultivation, increased the Head Tax by 50 percent, and continued construc- tion of infrastructure. Before the Great Depression, traditional agriculture received minimal attention primarily because of high transportation and tariff costs. The major foci of the colonial state were on labor recruitment, food production (in the western region), and mining exploration. Rich veins of tin had been discovered in eastern Rwanda in the 19205, and several Belgian banks and business firms provided capital for this industry.1 The provisioning of eastern Zaire from western Rwanda was also well established during this period. Colonial officials were encouraged to comply with European requests for labor, and Union MiniEre du Haut Katanga was the prime contractor of African labor in the ocuntry in the late 19205. Rwandans emigrated as laborers to British territories as well. The state's reorganization program in the 19305 reduced corvee and prestations even further, centralized geographical units for better administration, and replaced chiefs and consolidated chieftaincies. These measures allegedly standardized and regulated a system in which 355 Belgian officials and the Batutsi elite coexisted, or dual colonialism, so to speak. But in any event, together they controlled a doubly exploitative system in which the Bahutu peasantry were totally subordinated. Transforming the pro- ductive and administrative system created profound social changes, and a dual system of over-rule served to retard the expectations of the Bututsi oligarchy and to contain the aspirations of the African population. While the European administrators monitored the colonial system as a whole, the Batutsi supervised the productive effort of the African population. The key to the whole system, however, was the effective management from the top and compliance from the notables who dominated the masses below. With reorganization completed, the colonial state proceeded with its coffee campaign. The government's decision to extend coffee cultivation stemmed partly from a reassessment by the metropole of the African's role in agricultural production and partly from the effects of the Great Depression. As the Belgian process of modernization began, the metropolitan government soon realized that "civilizing" was an expensive business, and they were unable to provide all the funds, particularly during the 19303. Belgian officials concluded that "civil- izing" must be paid for out of profits or the "undelivered portion" of the African wages. This increment, plowed back into the country, into roads and transportation, conservation measures, health and educational facilities, became the u I _ 356 “civilizing sinking fund." As the metropole's needs increased for more visible signs of economic progress, more and more Rwandans were forced into the modern sector to facilitate its development, and consequently more and more demands were placed on the Bahutu to maintain the solvency of the colony. Cash crop production was only part of this process. Because coffee had been produced on a limited scale since 1920, the decision to extend cultivation in Rwanda did not need feasibility studies, and by 1930 there was consid- erable evidence that production could be profitable. World market prices of 20 BF per kilo had encouraged Belgian speculators to invest heavily in arabica coffee plantations in the Kivu and Ituri during the late 19203. It was then rumored that the Kivu could become another Kenya: excellent climate, the condition of the land, and the relative ease by which cheap labor could be recruited caused official optimism. Despite some initial setbacks the official government campaign was quite successful. Free seedlings were distrib- uted; the Agricultural Service supplied demonstrations on mulching techniques and built coffee nurseries throughout the country. Although coffee prices fell during the 19305, production increased to 70 tons in 1932, 152 tons in 1933, and 223 tons in 1934.2 Within these years, the average price paid for African coffee ranged from 2.50 BF to 4 BF 357 per kilo. By 1935 the volume of exports also experienced increases in cotton, produce, beeswax, hides, and tin. Therefore, other sectors of the economy were expanding as well. Reliance on African agriculture, however, was a major preoccupation in official colonial circles long before the Great Depression forced the metropole to take action; and even before African commerical production had matured, the authorities decided to discourage European settlement and their encroachment into the coffee and tobacco industries. The population density was already high in areas where the soil was relatively fertile, and European settlers and commercial enterprises aggravated pressures on the land. African labor was much cheaper and transportation and tariff costs were high. Also, a total reliance on Africans meant that savings could be made on those services that Europeans required and expected. The colonial debate in the mid-19205 brought the matter to a head. Those against the administration's position called for massive infusions of private capital and industrialization, while proponents emphasized African agri- culture, not industrial development. The debate continued until 1933, when the metropole announced a policy favoring African agriculture and moderate industrial development. Naturally the settlers were alarmed by this pronouncement and immediately mobilized to protect their interests. Between 1927 and 1939, European planters in Stanleyville, 358 Bukavu, and the Kivu and the representatives at Brussels consistently voiced opposition to African commercial cultivation. White settlers and especially coffee planters had reason to fear competition from African planters. The depression had reduced prices for agricultural commodities generally, and Brazil's manipulation of the coffee market subjected the already low prices to extreme fluctuations. Moreover, coffees from Belgian Africa were the least preferred in Europe and in the metropole. Consequently African competition was completely undesirable. As the Great Depression worsened and budget deficits increased, the administration at home became more conscious of cost effi- ciency. Previously, financial assistance to planters was confined to grants and loans; Africans received famine relief and expenditures for normal education and public works.3 In the past, private enterprises were given special incentive to invest in the "empire." Some firms received extensive land concessions for growing coffee and the black wattle tree valuable for its tannin extract.4 Those who adopted the "civilizing" principle or collaborated with African farmers gained concessions of 500 hectares with 99 year leases. Individual holders had a virtual monopoly on African labor and produce within a limited (15 km. radius) "protective zone"; companies had 70,000 hectares with access to African labor and the exclusive right to purchase the commercial crops from African farmers. Participants were 359 only required to install a processing mill and to furnish schools, quarantine stations, and seeds for their African charges, as part of the social contract. These zones were devised, however, to also eliminate Asian and Indian competition and to rationalize economic development.5 During the Depression, European settlers were perceived as a drain on the treasury because of their repeated demands for subsidies, tariff reductions, and regulations to assure even cheaper labor costs. The relief was expensive for the metropole to provide, and it believed that its efforts to extend decrees to either cancel export duties on certain commercial commodities, such as vegetables, palm oil, and sugar cane, or to provide exemptions to cotton fabrics manu- factured in Belgian Africa were more than adequate.6 Goods coming from the colonies already entered the metropole duty free, and a decree of 1934 leavied a 300 BF per ton export duty on unroasted coffee entering the "empire,"7 in order to restrict the entry of foreign coffees, which might be re-exported duty free into Belgium. Authorities also sought other ways to reduce costs. Land reclamation became an integral component of the agri- cultural program. Chemical fertilizer, however, was not considered, because of the terrain and the traditional nature of agriculture in Rwanda, and because of its expense. Since famine would disrupt the productive cycle, the resident governor had the power to require each able bodied, adult male to maintain 35 acres of seasonal and 15 acres of 360 non-seasonal food crops. The latter included manioc, to be replaced by potatoes in areas above 1900 meters.8 Lacking suitable storage, the selection of such durable crops was a wise choice. While reluctant to graft a capitalist model of production onto their traditional forms, Africans were able to adjust. Rwandan farmers accepted imposed crops, the burden of taxation to support the colonial infrastructure, traditional dues and corvee, and akagi for the modern sector. Even today many remarked that coffee was beneficial, for it "gave us money to pay taxes and to buy things." Economic development assisted some Africans, and was apparently beneficial to the country. Trade figures for 1935 indicated that Rwanda was thoroughly integrated into the international market economy. Export earnings for that year were 45 million francs, 70 percent from Belgium and the remainder from Japan. Imports were valued at 39 million francs, of which 10.3 millions francs were attributed to Belgium and 18.1 million francs to Japan.9 Surplus revenues from international trade were invested in the country only to the extent that they facilitated the flow of goods to markets overseas; otherwise, profits were retained or gar- nished by the colonial state. Some funds were repatriated to Belguim in order to repay development loans, but most revenue was used to maintain the colonial government. As we have seen, the general expansion of trade by the colonial state was a sign of Rwanda's transition from a pre-capitalist to a semi-capitalist economy during the imperial phase. 361 Compulsory cash crops and the sale of foodstuffs stimulated economic growth, but prevented the rational evolution of a diversified economy. Without rigid control by the state, the international economy and free market forces might possibly have activated Rwanda's agricultural economy along different lines. But once the basic infrastructure for trade was established the colonial state had fulfilled its own needs for revenues by encouraging imperial trade and commerce. Africans were only marginal beneficiaries, and only those who could effectively manipulate the system benefitted. Dependence upon coffee to provide foreign exchange in a structurally imbalanced economy continues to plague Rwanda. Between 1929 and 1941, economic legislation was based on the belief that Africans could only be farmers, and political changes and social actions consequently barred all effective participation by the Bahutu and the Batutsi in industry and commerce. Compulsory cultivation and the pervasive colonial state, embodied in the metropole and in Belgian civil servants in the mandate, stifled the spirit of initiative and innovation within the traditional systems. Nowhere in Rwanda did chiefs, notables and peasant farmers take responsibility in economic production. They did not even exercise any real responsibility in the performance of menial tasks, such as public works, irrigation projects, and in the construction and upkeep of stretches of roads and of public buildings, which were basically the business of 362 Rwandans. Belgian colonialism effectively eliminated direct African participation in all spheres of influence and decision-making. Economic planning, as well as the pur- chasing, processing, and marketing of coffee and other export crops, was executed by Europeans with the help of mainly unskilled African labor, quasi—governmental agencies and societies, and Arab, Hindu, Greek and Indian merchants, although Asians were phased out of the export trade after 1930 and limited to intermediaries in the domestic economy. At independence, when the colonial state apparatus was removed in 1962, the economic structure collapsed. The new government was unable to function because of lack of experience. Almost all production was abandoned, and coffee and other produce was left in the fields to rot; during the period of transition and consolidation, African simply refused to produce or to tend to their fields. Because of "indirect administration," Rwandans were ill-equipped by training or experience to operate or to recycle the dregs left by the Belgians into productive capacity. Belgian colonialism effectively had eliminated influential African participation in the world market economy. Thus, after independence, there was no African management, and Rwanda continued to depend upon expatriates to perform essential functions in the commercial sector. In the final analysis, the absence of an African management class in Rwanda, able to take charge, has much to 363 do with the excessive intervention from the state (both in the metropole and in the colony) during the colonial period. State intervention successfully converted coercive force over Rwandans into a legitimate authority, which Africans reluctantly accepted. But while this conversion promoted change, it also preserved continuity within the traditional areas. The retention of the feudal system and the onset of colonialism was responsible for impeding the formation of a viable middle sector, because it distorted the process of primitive accumulation. Since there were no white settlers in any great numbers in Rwanda and little possibility of attracting foreign capital, the state's land policy and taxation on African households, designed to force workers into the capitalist sector, were used instead to foster the development of a viable African middle sector, capable of sustaining the development of the country. Failure to dis- member the feudal system, coupled with the Great Depression, meant that valuable labor reserves had to serve two masters-- the state and the traditional Batutsi oligarchy. African labor was used to maintain the solvency of the colony, as well as the life style of the Batutsi notables, but there was little opportunity for the peasantry to acquire capital. Even expanded peasant production during the 1930s failed to transform the feudal system or to encourage economic specialization. The oligarchy was too entrenched, and the Bahutu could not be completely divorced from 364 subsistence agriculture, primarily because the risks were too great: peasant life was precarious. Moreover, while the Bahutu could be made to produce for foreign markets and could dominate the coffee economy from 1931 to 1939, and while earned export income and other revenues increased annually until the Second World War, the state could not create sufficient security to wean them away from subsistence agriculture and toward economic specialization. The environment was a limiting factor in this process, but state and Batutsi exactions were more debilitating. CONCLUSIONS Notes lAlison L. DesForges, "Defeat Is the Only Bad News: Rwanda Under Musiinga, 1896-1931," (Ph.D. thesis, Yale University, 1972), p. 323. 2Rapportpresenté'par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société des Nations au sujet de l'Administration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant l'Annee 1934 (Brussels, 1935), p. 131. Production totals for 1933 and 1934 include tonnage for Burundi. 3Rapport 1924, p. 15; Rapport 1925, p. 104; Ra ort 1929, p. 61; and Edmund Le Plae, "Les Plantations de CafE au Congo Belge, leur Histoire (1881-1935), leur Importance," Institute Royal Colonial Belge memoire 8, 111 (1936), p. 225. 4DesForges, "Defeat Is the Only Bad News," p. 323. 5Rapport 1929, p. 39; J. De Rykman de Betz, "La Mise en Valeur de Ruanda-Urundi," Agriculture et Eleyage au Congo Belge IV, 4 (February 22, 1930), pp. 52-3; and "Documenta- tion sur le Kivu et le Ruanda-Urundi," Agriculture et Elevage au Congo Belge, VI, 16 (November 26, 1932), pp. 183-6. 6E. Dubois, "La Politique Economique Coloniale, 1932- 34," Bulletin l'Institute des Sciences Economiques, VI, 2 (1935), pp. 133-34. Also, companies that were ill- conceived, ill-directed, or founded on pure speculation collapsed. 7Dubois, "La Politique Economique Coloniale, 1932-34," p. 134. 8A. Becquet, "Moyens mis en Oeuvre et les Resultats Obtenus dans le Lutte contre la Famine au Ruanda," Journees d'Agronomie Coloniale, (June 23-24, 1933), p. 4. 9"Territoire sous Mandat," Congo, I (January-May 1938) p. 228. 365 APPENDIX Table A-1. APPENDIX I Volume and Value of Imports, 1922-1959. 366 839138 SONVHd :IO SNOI'I'IIIN 0.. m w ON mm on mm Ow mc Om mm 00 mm Oh wk on mm om mm 00.. mm #0 mm NM .amaeimmae .mupoeeH to m=2e> pew me=Ho> .e-< peppy mam Tumor wm 5 on mm an 3 mm mm «a nu T j Ijrr111 [j A u q _ A _ — — 4 d _ x0 \x. I'I.\ O O\O/0\ .mzot mecca! out... 5023.“: 9:22.01 WE On. 5: H NHanmmmd. OQNOIDQ'NNF SNOL OIHLEW :IO SCINVSflOHJ. Thousand of Metric Tons 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 367 F — imports (tons) — — imports (francs) "— ~ / / J l I J l l l l 38 40 42 44 46 48 50 52 54 56 58 Years 1 936-1959 2600 2400 2200 2000 1 800 1 600 1 400 1 200 1 000 800 600 400 200 Millions of Francs Belges 368 839138 SONVHJ :IO SNOIT‘IIW Ow mp ON mN on mm 0v mv Om mm Do we Oh ms om mm Om mm 009 mam TNNGP wm mm 3 an an 5 on mm an R mm mm cu nu . _ _ _ a e _ . J 4 1 . _ \u - a .\ 1 .l \\ [I \‘Z‘ I file °¢\/.\ °/°/°/\ l l o l 1 ex 0 1 .. J r I 1 l j l 1 $20.: memOnxm our:- 1 u .mozgu. mhmOexm ollo 1 umOnxm mmhcmVflNF amwteezeeze SNOJ. OIHLSW :IO SCINVSDOHJ. Thousands of Metric Tons 369 200 — I\J exports (tons) l 180 _ — — exports (francs) I 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 O—’ l I l l l l l l I l 1 —l 38 4o 42 44 46 48 so 52 54 56 58 Years 1 936-1 959 2600 2400 2200 2000 1 800 1 600 1 400 1 200 1 000 800 ' Millions of Francs Belges 600 400 200 APPENDIX II Table B-l(a) Volume of Foreign Trade 1927-1960 HH Nanmmm< 370 meno> 2. me mm mm 5 _ A a — _ x, \ \ / \\ / \/ > x x \ < , r /\l A , omcoo ego—om on 2398 .. l l 09.00 cu_m_om E0: 3.89:. I 89.89 «not. .538“. to oE:_o> E To «an... ..3 France ON 0? cm on ape”, JO suo; omen “no; )0 °/o 371 mm 93> cacao ana-om 3 3698 II l 0950 c3900 Ea: 3.2.8. I comfsuow oboe... p.990“. .0 oE20> .3 Tm 030... to. «canto ow om 00.. soueu saB|aa u! spell go ameA "210110 0/0 372 emo> mach 050.2 E canned» il l moan.“— moEom c. o2m> com Thump one; c990". .0 oE=_o> .37m 2an to. ”nacho oBuoo uegfilaa won suodwu "210140 0/0 APPENDIX I II Table C-l. Principle Food Products Exported to the Belgian Congo from Ruanda-Urundi, 1928 - 1938 APPENDIX III 373 Table C-l. Principle Food Products Exported to the Belgian Congo from Ruanda-Urundi, 1928-1938. . All Other Cattle Livestock Food Products* Francs Francs Francs Belges Belges Metric Belges Year Head (1,000) Head (1,000) Tons (1,000) 1928a 1,068 213.6 360 22.4 1,018.5 1,223.2 1929b 1,146 290.8 -- -- 269 506.9 1932C 15,860 2,755.8 54,517 1,104.9 708 412.2 1933d 6,999 978.1 25,969 476.2 1,306 678.0 1934e 3,103 452.6 13,811 208.9 2,709 1,315.5 1935f 4,050 708.7 22,750 386.7 2,256 1,814.8 19369 33,600 7,140.0 115,000 2,070.0 2,244 2,591.1 1937h 27,000 9,600.0 34,750 1,055.0 4,652 4,918.6 19381 28,000 10,350.0 50,000 1,820.0 5,751 3,344.5 *Products included are: beans, peas, sorghum, manioc flour, rice, fruits, palm oil, butter, coffee, peanuts, palm nuts, dry fish, maize flour, maize and wheat. SOURCES AND NOTES: EPapport presenté'par Ze Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société'des Nations au sujet db l'Administration de Ruanda-Urundi pendant Z'Anne’e 1928 (Brussels, 1929), 96. tliapport 1929, 100. Also 65 kilos of raw meat were exported at a value of BF 4,527. cNo itemized totals for 1930 and 1931. Products for 1932 included 155 pigs, valued at BF 19,500, and 3,600 chickens, valued at BP 7,200. .mqmor61932, pp. 128 and 130. Table at at at at at BF BF BF BF BF 374 C-1. Continued <1%1ppori: 2933, pp. 162 and 35,840 were exported. 7iapp0rt 1934, pp. 148 and 13,800 were exported. E’apport 1934, pp. 149 and 52,220 were exported. gRapport 1936, pp. 153 and 39,000 were exported. rRapport 1937, pp. 158 and JRapport 1938, pp. 168 and 50,000 were exported. 164. 150. 151. 155. 160. 171. Also Also Also Also Also 265 120 373 200 283 pigs, pigs, pigs. pigs, pigs. valued valued valued valued valued Table D-l. APPENDIX IV The Principal Tax Receipts in Rwanda and Burundi, 1925-1959 (in Belgian francs). fillIIIIIIIII lillll| .Amocmum cmfiwaom cwv ommaummma .Hpcsuzm pom mpcmam cw mudwouom me Hmdfioawum one .Hlo «Home SONVHd SNOI'I'IIW mc \ «no. \ 33 \ one, \ mam . \ mum. 83 82 name 0 omen: omen: one»: one”: one»: omenupkmenaekmvn: p. ._. d L... e .. w 1 w .. 6 m. 1 m m w m 180.com w m. m . . 168 con F I .093 r. W. H... r .I r. 80 A. w s m 136.08.." c m 0 P w. L .v m ...... w 186.636 . 6 B s 1 8068.6 «3 F 1 F 3 e . f r F E ... I So can m w u m .... A c. S I. a a 1 . ... ... . 108 can a. e m m e w. .u. w e. 18068. ta. 9 I. m e. m m. flooodoodu o .o. M Iobodéo§h 85803 6230 .o 1000;5va 3.3». d .3... .2520.- . o \v .3... 2:02.. .c ‘fiuooodoofifl w xoh 2:00 . n €62.66 . « 180.0363 5:. one... cant; . .. 421686363 >H XHazmmm< SONVSHOHJ. OBHOan-I SNOITIIW N31. 376 mm \K gawk «mark moap\ snap Qnaw\ mncw\ gaw\ ”flap 1 mvnuw- menu...‘ mvnww omenflw carvnflw nmvnuw cmwflup cm‘nflw l- ll W. i m. _l - l o c. e m 1 1 1 m n" W 8 m .6. I. ID 8 9 9 .I. C W. I m m u. 0 A. .1 d a L L I L L 1 L L l I m \ o f n ..u 823.: £830 . o cox-h .- 33: .252: . n nah 2:02.. . v nah 0:30 . n V. ass—Eon . a 5:. use: cacti . . SONVSflOl-IJ. OSUONHH St 8 SI. ZZ'OVL 3 (9 '- NV SNOITIIW SNOITIIW N31. 377 wc Swap mvan «#0 w w mwaw MN _. 30w m nap mgr mvnuw near an w scar nap o Sodom 80.88. p 80.3...“ 08.086 68.08... 30.8»... Sodom..." 4. H 80.63.» e W 08.08. pa 8 9994/ ll 000.8066 08.89:" OOO.§.MV ZZ 0) 913-09 0191 88 0% ZV'OS 0391. 82000: E325 . a 23.3. a use: .2382. . n .3... 2:00... . Q .3... 0.300 . a 3.3028 . N nah use: coat; . p 93 0! VV'OS 0) 08 §.§.mu w 09 0199-911 80.80fi0fl OO0.00¢.mmN SONVSHOHJ. O3HONnH SNOITIIW SNOIT‘IIW N31 378 mm ”map Np Char mvnuw avaw nvfluw O wnaw mvnup Dmmw vmaw «v mmaw «map 6 w nXX1000 OOOKXXKQ 80.80;. 08.80.... 4. w 8.80.0 . N O 08.8. E 8 80.806“ 08.80:.» 08.8.8 I. .. m w. m 08.808 p m .. .. .. 328... £230 . o m m w m .2...» a .3... .28.... . 6 80.80.08 w n... n w no... 0500:. . v m u .1 5 2:8 . a 08.80 .08 em m m 8.020.. . a L l .3». use... soot: . p .6 z O 0 suomm suomm SONVSDOHL O3HONDH N31. 379 30.000: 8830 . 0 09.0.. a .20: .2382. . .5. ask 0500:. . v .8... 2:00 . 0 >832: . N us... 000: c334 . w 0009 mvnN w 09103081 mm 000' 000 N w OVlOIOLl hmaw mfian 999W 09 0 000.000 000.000; §.§.N 000.00N.0 000.000.v 000.0006 000.0006 4. 000.000.0p W 000.000. ..N s 000.000.0N 000600.50 000.0006? 000.000.0N w 000.000.00N 000.000.00N SCI NVSflOHL O3HONnH SNOI'IWIW SNOITIIW N31. BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY A. BOOKS AND DISSERTATIONS Adolphus Frederick, duke of Mecklenburg-Schwerin. In the Heart of Africa. London; New York: Cassell, 1910. Amin, Samir. Unequal Development: An Essay on the Social Formations of Peripheral Capitalism. New York & London: Monthly Review Press, 1966. Anstey, Roger. King Leopold's Legacy: the Congo Under Belgian Rule, 1908-1960. London & New York : Oxford University Press, 1966. Bayton, W. H.; R. E. Downs; Yolande Jemai; S. E. Ross-Larson. A Report on Assistance to a National Maternal and Child Health and Family Planning Program in Rwanda. Washington, D. C.: 1981. Berger, Elena L. Labour, Race, and Colonial Rule:' the Copperbelt from 1924 to Independence. Oxford, England: Clarendon Press, 1974. Brett, E. A. Colonialism and Underdevelopment in East Africa: the Politics of Economic Change, 1919-1939. New York: NOK Publishers, Ltd., 1973. Cohen, William B. The French Encounter with Africans: White Response to Blacks, 1530—1880. Bloomington & London: Indiana University Press, 1980. Dak, O. A Geographical Analysis of the Distribution of Migrants in Uganda. Occasional Paper No. 11. Kampala: Makerere University College, Department of Geography, 1968. Des Forges, Alison L. "Defeat Is the Only Bad News: Rwanda Under Musinga, 1896-1931." Ph.D. thesis, Yale University, 1972. d'Hertefelt, Marcel and Andre Coupez. La royaute sacrée de l'ancien Rwanda. Tervuren: MusEe royal d'Afrique centrale, 1964. Elkan, Walter. Migrants and Proletarians: Urban Labour in the Economic Development of Uganda. London: Oxford University Press for the East African Institute of Social Research, 1960. 380 381 Elkan, Walter. The Economic Development of Uganda. London: Oxford University Press-Nairobi, 1961. Fetter, Bruce. "The Colonial Tie in the Making of Elisabethville." Ph.D. thesis, University of Wisconsin, 1968. . The Creation of Elisabethville, 1910-1940. Stanford: Hoover Institute Press, 1976. Gravel, Pierre B. "A Play for Power: Description of a Community in Eastern Rwanda." Ph.D. thesis, University of Michigan, 1962. Higginson, John E. "The Making of an African Working Class: the Union Miniere du Haut Katanga and the African Mine Workers, 1907-1945." Volumes I and II. Ph.D. thesis, University of Michigan, 1979. Howard, Rhoda. Colonialism and Underdevelopment in Ghana. New York: Africana Publishing Company, 1978. Kerken, Georges van der. La crise economique en Afrique belge. Brussels: E. Bruylant, 1931. Kimble, George H. T. Tropical Africa. Volume II. Society and Polity. Garden City, New York: Doubleday, 1962. LeMarchand,'Ren5. Rwanda and Burundi. London: Pall Mall Press, 1970. Leubuscher, Charlotte. Tanganyika Territory: a Study of Economic Policy Under Mandate. London: Oxford University Press for the Royal Institute of Inter- national Affairs, 1944. Linden, Ian, with Jane Linden. Church and Revolution in Rwanda. New York: Manchester University Press] Africana Publishing Company, 1977. Lord Hailey. An African Survey: a Study of Problems Arising in Africa South of the Sahara. London: Oxford University Press, 1938. Louis, William Roger. Ruanda-Urundi, 1884-1919. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1963. Maquet, Jacques J. The Premise of Inequality in Ruanda. London & New York: International African Institute, Oxford University, 1961. 382 Martelli, George. Leopold to Lumumba: a History of the Belgian Congo. London: Chapman & Hall Ltd., 1962. Michiels, A. and N. Laude. Notre Colonie: Congo belge et Ruanda-Urundi. Geographie et Notice Historique. Brussels: Edition Universelle (S.A.), 1949. Newbury, Catherine Atterbury. "The Cohesion of Oppression: a Century of Clientship in Kinyaga, Rwanda." Ph.D. thesis, University of Wisconsin-Madison, 1975. Reed, Harry A. "Cotton-Growing in Central Nyanza Province, Kenya, 1901-1939: an Appraisal of African Reactions to Imposed Government Policy." Ph.D. thesis, Michigan State University, 1975. Rodney, Walter. How Europe Underdeveloped Africa. Washington, D. C. : Howard University Press, 1974. Vail, David Jeremiah. "The Public Sector as Stimulus of Innovation Adoption in African Smallholder Agriculture: a Case Study in Teso District Uganda." Ph.D. thesis, Yale University, 1971. Vali, Jamal. "The Role of Cotton and Coffee in Uganda's Economic Development." Ph.D. thesis, Stanford University, 1976. Wagoner, Fred E. "Nation Building in Africa: a Description and Analysis of the Development of Rwanda." Ph.D. thesis, American University, 1968. The World Bank. Agricultural Sector Review. Rwanda Report 1377-RW. Regional Project Department, East Africa Regional Office, June 30, 1977. Wrigley, C.C. Crops and Wealth in Uganda: a Short Agrarian History. Kampala: East African Institute of Social Research, 1959. B. ARTICLES AND PAPERS Bart, Frangois. "Le Café'dans l'Agriculture rwandaise: l'exemple de Kidahire (Runyinya)," Les Cahiers d'Outre-Mer XXXIII, No. 132 (October-December 1980), pp. 301-317. Berman, B. J. and J. M. Lonsdale. "Crises of Accumulation, Coercion and the Colonial State: the Development of the Labor Control System in Kenya, 1919-1929," Canadian Journal of African Studies XIV, No. 1 (1980), pp. 55-81. 383 Bessel, J. M. "Nyabingi," Uganda Journal VI (1938-39), pp. 73-86. Bryceson, Deborah Fahy. "Peasant Commodity Production in Post-Colonial Tanzania," African Affairs LXXXI, No. 325 (October 1982), pp. 547-567. Chandra, Bipan. "Colonialism, Stages of Colonialism and the Colonial State," Journal of Contemporary Asia X, No. 3 (1980). pp. 272-285. Chretien, Jean-Pierre. "Des sedentaires devenus migrants: les motifs des departs des Burundais et des Rwandais vers 1' Uganda (1920-1960)," Culture et developpement X, No. l (1978). PP. 71-101. Foster-Carter, Aidan. "From Rostow to Gunder Frank: Conflicting Paradigms in the Analysis of Under- development," World Development 4 (1976), pp. 167-180. . "The Modes of Production Controversy," New Left Review, No. 107 (January-February 1978), pp. . "Neo-Marxist Approaches to Development and Under- development," in E. de Kadt and G. Welbams, eds. Sociology and Development. London: Tavistock Publications, 1974, pp. 67-105. Gildea, Ray Y., Jr. and Alice Taylor. "Rwanda and Burundi," Focus XIII, No. 6 (February 1963), pp. 1-6. Hance, William A. and Irene S. van Dongen. "Matadi: Focus of Belgian African Transport," Annals of the Association of American Geographers vol. 48, No. 1 (March 1958), pp. 41-72. Heggath, Richard. "From Modernization Theory to Public Policy: Continuity and Change in the Political Sciences of Political Development," a paper presented to the 49th ANZAAS Congress, Sociology Section. Auckland, New Zealand, January 1979. Heimo, Marcel Ch. "Réflexion sur les conditions et les perspectives du développement ébonomique au Rwanda," Genéve-Afrique VII, No. l (1968), pp. 7-29. Hillman, Jimmye S. "The Role of Export Cropping in Less Developed Countries," Journal of Agricultural Economics LXIII, No. 2 (May 1981), pp. 375-383. 384 Jewsiewicki, Bogumil. "Le colonat agricole Européen au Congo belge, 1910- 1960: questions politiques et economiques," Journal of African History XX, No. 4 (1970), PP. 559- 571. "Notes sur l'Histoire socio-Economique du Congo," Etudes d'Histoire africaine III (1972), pp. 209-241. . "Zaire enters the world system: its colonial incorporation as the Belgian Congo, 1885-1960," in Guy Gran and Galen Hull, eds. Zaire: the Political Economy of Underdevelopment. New York: Praeger, 1979, pp. Kagame, Alexis. "Le code Esoterique de la Dynastié’du Ruanda," Zaire IV (1947), pp. 363-386. Legassick, Martin. "South Africa: Capital Accumulation and Violence," Economy and Society III, No. 3 (August 1974), pp. 253-291. LePlae, Edmund. "Les Plantations de Cafe au Congo belge: leur histoire (1881-1935), leur importance," Institut Royal Colonial Belge, mémoires 8, III (1936), pp. 1-248. Leurquin, Phillipe. "La vie économique du Paysan ruanda, l'exemple de Karama, Nyaruguru," Zaire II (January 1959). pp. 41-67. Leys, Colin. "African Economic Development in Theory and Practice," Daedalus III, No. 2 (Spring 1982), pp. 99-124. Lonsdale, John and Bruce Berman. "Coping with the Contra- dictions: the Development of the Colonial State in Kenya, 1895-1914," qurnal of African History XX, No. 4 (1979). PP. 487-505. Lopans, Jean and David Seddon. "Marxism and Anthropology: A Preliminary Survey," in D. §eddon, ed. Relations of Production. London: Cass; lTotowa, N. J. distributed by Biblio Distribution Centr_/, 1978, PP- Maquet, Jacques J. "Rwanda Castes," in Arthur Tuden and Leonard Platnicov, eds. Social Stratification in Africa. New York: Free Press, 1973, pp. 93-124. Molitor, G. "Campagnes de propagande pour 1' Introduction et le developpement de la Culture du Cafeier Arabica chez 1' indigene du Ruanda-Urundi," Journees d' Agronomie colonial (Louvain, 1937), pp. 238- 249. -3... .1“..-— L' ‘1 3;." 385 Morris, M. L. "The Development of Capitalism in South African Agriculture: Class Struggle in the Country- side," Economy and Society V, No. 3 (August 1976), pp. 292-343. Newbury, Catherine A. "Ubureetwa and Thangata: Comparative Colonial Perspectives," in Colloque de Bujumbura (4-10 septembre 1979). La Civilisation ancienne des peuples des Grands Lacs. Paris: Editions Karthala; Bujumbura: Centre de CiVilisation Burundaises, 1981, pp. 138-147. Peemans, Jean-Phillipe. "Capital Accumulation in the Congo under Colonialism: the Role of the State," in Peter Duignan and L. H. Gann, eds. Colonialism in Africa, 1870-1960. Volume Four: The Economics of_Colonialism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1975, pp. 165-212. Phillips, J. E. T. "The Nyabingi: An Anti—European Secret Society in Africa," Congo I (1928), pp. 310—521. Powesland, P. S. "History of Migration in Uganda," in Audrey I. Richards, ed. Economic Development and Tribal Change: A Study of Immigrant Labour in Buganda. Cambridge: W. Heffer & Sons Ltd. for the East African Institute of Social Research, 1954, PP- "Le programme economique dans le Ruanda-Urundi," Congo I (June 1921). pp. 253-269. "La Rapport sur 1' Administration belge au Ruanda-Urundi pendant 1' annee 1923, " Congo I (January-May 1924), pp. 747- 757. "Rapport sur 1' Administration belge du Ruanda-Urundi pendant 1' annee 1934, " Congo II (June-December 1935), pp. 765- 778. Richards, A. I. "The Travel Routes of the Travellers," in Audrey I. Richards, ed. Economic Development and Tribal Change: A Study of Immigrant Labour in Buganda. Cambridge: W. Heffer & Sons Ltd. for the East African Institute of Social Research, 1954, PP- Ryckmans, Pierre. "Le problEme politique au Ruanda-Urundi," Congo I, No. 3 (1925), pp. 120-162. 386 Sladden, George E. and L. Michel. "Methodes de Commerciali- sation du Cafe arabica produit par les Indigenes du Ruanda-Urundi," Numero special du Bulletin agricole du Congo belge XLIII (1952). "Territoires sous Mandat," Congo I (January-May 1937), pp. 184-191. "Territoires sous Mandat," Congo I (January-May 1938), pp. 223-230. "Territoires sous Mandat," Congo I (January-May 1939), pp. 99-106. van Tichelin, H. E. "ProblEmes du Developpement economique du Ruanda-Urundi," Zaire II (May 1957), pp. 451-474. Vellut, Jean Luc. "Rural Poverty in Western Shaba, c. 1890- 1930," in Robin Palmer and Neil Parson, eds. The Roots of Rural Poverty in Central and South AfEIEa. Berkeley & Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1977, pp. 294-316. Weinstein, Warren. "Ruanda-Urundi (Rwanda-Burundi)," in Gregory Henderson, Richard Ned Lebow, and John G. Stoessinger, eds. Divided Nations in a Divided World. New York: David McKay Company, Inc., 1974, pp. Young, Crawford. "Patterns of Social Conflict: State, Class, and Ethnicity," Daedalus III, No. 2, (Spring 1982). Pp. 71-98. C. THE LEAGUE OF NATIONS AND THE UNITED NATIONS Permanent Mandates Commission, 7th Session, New York, 1925. Permanent Mandates Commission, 16th Session, New York, 1929. Permanent Mandates Commission. Minutes and Reports, 18th Session, New York, 1938. U. N. Visiting Mission to East Africa, 1949. Report on Ruanda-Urundi. Trusteeship Council, 4th Session, Supplement, No. 2, 1950. United Nations Trusteeship Council. Study of Population, Land Utilization and Land System in Ruanda-Urundi, prepared by the Secretariat to the Committee on Rural Economic Development of the Trust Territories, 26 March 1957. T/AC.36/L.60. 387 D. CONGO MANUSCRIPTS, MICHIGAN STATE UNIVERSITY, EAST LANSING, MICHIGAN Folder No. 9. "Figures coloniales, Georges Sandrart: Ancien Resident du Ruanda et de l'Urundi, Pourquoi Pas, No. 1 (November 2, 1952), pp. 107-108. E. CONSORTIUM FOR AFRICA MICROFILM PROJECT (CAMP), CHICAGO, ILLINOIS MF 1552. Rwanda. Miscellaneous Correspondence, 1916-1919. Notice sur le Ruanda--l9l6. Film No. 34, Reel 1. J. M. Derscheid Collection. Territoires du Ruanda-Urundi. Residence du Ruanda. Territoire d' Astrida. Rapport de Sortie de charge, etabli par Monsieur Andre Servranckx, administrateur territorial de 1 ere cl. ayant administré’le territoire d' Astrida depuis 1e 27 aofit 1932. Astrida, September 26, 1933. Film No. 34, Reel 2. J. M. Derscheid Collection. Territoire du Ruanda-Urundi. Résidence du Ruanda: Territoire d'Astrida. Rapport de Sortie de Charge. September 23, 1933. Territoire de Biumba. Rapport de Sortie de Charge, de l'Administrateur territorial, A. J. F. Stevens, du territoire de Biumba. October 12, 1933. Film No. 34, Reel 3. J. M. Derscheid Collection. Territoire de Ruanda-Urundi. Residence du Ruanda: Territoire de Nyanza. Rapport etabli en reponse au questionnaire adressé en 1929, par M. 1e Gouverneur du Ruanda-Urundi a 1' Administrateur du Territoire d' Astrida. Territoire de Nyanza. Rapport etabli en reponse au questionnaire adressé’en 1929, par M. 1e Gouverneur du Ruanda-Urundi a 1' Administrateur du territoire de Nyanza, M. Lenaerts. R. J. L. Schmidt. Rapport politique de territoire de Kigali, 1933. 388 ME 1552. Rwanda. Miscellaneous Archival Material, 1925-1941: Developpement moral et social Rapport annuel zfi.d E rtie: Protection du Travail. 17 - des indigenes. 3 Pa Chapitre III: Instruction publique et d'etablissements d'enseignment ZP-d;/- Province du Ruanda-Urundi. Residence du Ruanda. No. 840/org. 5. Ordre de service, 1e resident du Ruanda, Morteham. Kigali, April 13, 1927. Province du Ruanda-Urundi. Residence du Ruanda. No. 1117/P.I.C. Monsieur 1e Délegue de Ruhengeri, 1e resident du Ruanda, G. Morteham. Kigali, May 22, 1928. Résidence du Ruanda. Territoire de Lubengera. No. 39/P.I. Monsieur 1e résident, 1e Déléguél Gitebe, January 18, 1931. Pro-Justitia. Territoire du Ruanda-Urundi. ADéposition/. Ruhengeri, March 2, 1932. Territoire du Ruanda-Urundi. Residence du Ruanda. No. 14/R. Annexe I: 1'inspection de la S/Chefferie- Rubindo a fait l'objet d'un rapport spécial en date du 15/1 dernier. Ruhengeri, January 23, 1937. Territoire du Ruanda-Urundi. RéSidence du Ruanda. No. 87/P.I.G.-44. Sous-chef Rubindo (Mulera), M. Rubbens, administrateur d'territoire. Ruhengeri, February 1, 1937. F. NATIONAL UNIVERSITY OF RWANDA, BUTARE, RWANDA Anonymous. Historique et Chronologie du Ruanda. AKabgayi/, 1956. Codere, Helen. "The Biography of an African Society, Rwanda: based on Forty-Eight Rwandan Autobiographies," Institut National de Recherche Scientifique, Publication No. 12 (1973). Kagame, Alexis. Yuhi Musinga: un Regne mouvemente. Unpublished manuscript. Leroy, Pierre. Legislation du Ruanda-Urundi. Usumbura (Bujumbur§/: s. 1., 1949. 389 Murego, Donat. [La revolution ruandaise, 1959-1962: Essai d'interpretation. Louvain: Publications de l'Institut des Sciences politiques et sociales, 1975. Reisdorff, I. Enquetes fonciéres au Ruanda. Texte polycopié, 1952. Ruzindana, Emmanuel. L'éyolution du commerce au Rwanda du dernier quart du XIXéme siécle 5'1950. Louvain: mémoire de licence, polycopié, 1974. Twagirayezu, Ephrem. "Le café’arabica et 1e developpement economique du Rwanda et du Burundi." Université' Lovanium de Leopoldville, Faculte des Sciences politique, sociales et economiques, 1964. G. ROYAL LIBRARY, BRUSSELS, BELGIUM Agriculture et Elevage au Congo belge et dans 1e Colonies tropicales et subtropicales: Deuxiéme annee, No. 18 (September 8, 1929), pp. 208-215. SixiEme année, No. 14 (October 15, 1932), pp. 158-162. Septiéme annee, No. 1 (January 1934), p. 3. "Agriculture indigEne: grandes lignes du programme agricole du Gouvernement," Neuviéme annee, No. 5 (May 1935). PP. 72-73. Alloncius, C.-J. "Le Marché'du Café E'Anvers, 12 novembre 1935. Rapport de la Banque belge d'Afrique," Neuvieme année, No. 12 (December 1935), p. 185. Becquet, A. "L'Organisation du Service de l'Agriculture au Congo belge," Treiziéme annee, No. 7 (July 1939): PP- 97-98. Brock, Raymond. "Le café'arabica et 1e Kivu," Neuviéme annee, No. 1 (January 1935), pp. 1-4. "Le Culture du Cafeier arabica au Ruanda-Urundi," Huitiéme annee, No. 1 (January 1934). p. 13. "La Culture du Cafeier par les IndigEnes du Ruanda- Urundi," Dixiéme annee, No. 3 (March 1935), p. 34. 390 "D6clarations de M. 1e Gouverneur General Ryckmans," Neuviéme ann6e, No. 12 (December 1935), pp. 184-185. De Ryckman de Betz, J. "La mise en valeur du Ruanda- Urundi," Quatrieme ann6e, No. 4 (February 22, 1930), pp. 52- 53. . "La mise en valeur du Ruanda-Urundi," QuatriEme anneé, No. 8 (April 19, 1930), pp. 121-123, and 125. "Documentation sur le Kivu et 1e Ruanda-Urundi," Sixieme ann6e, No. 16 (November 26, 1932), pp. 183-186. "Documentation sur 1e Kivu et le Ruanda-Urundi. R6union de l'Union Agricole du Kivu du jeudi 2 mars 1933," SeptiEme ann6e, No. 5 (April 1933), p. 52. "Documentation sur le Kivu et le Ruanda-Urundi. Union agricole des Régions du Kivu. Reunion du 12 avril 1933, " Septieme ann6e, No. 7 (June 1933). p. 78. "Documentation sur le Kivu et le Ruanda-Urundi. Union agricole des Régions du Kivu," Huitiéme ann6e, No. 1 (January 1934), pp. 2-4. "Documentation sur le Kivu et le Ruanda-Urundi. Assembl6e g6n6ra1e du 13 fevrier 1935," Neuvféme ann6e, No. 4 (April 1935), pp. 51-53. Gille, Albert.N "Les Cultures indigenes de caf6 en Urundi," Heitieme ann6e, No. 2 (February 1934), pp. 22- 23. "Les Plantations de Caf6 du Ruanda-Urundi," TroisiEme ann6e, No. 6 (March 23, 1929), pp. 88-89. "La politique du caf6 dans les territoires sous mandat," Neuvieme ann6e, No. (August 1935), pp. 123-124. "Superficie des plantations de caf6iers au Congo belge et au Ruanda-Urundi," Neuvieme ann6e, No. 1 (January 1935), p. 12. "Union agricole des Régions du Kivu. Rapport pour la Séance du jeudi 23 fevrier 1933," Septiéme ann6e, No. 6 (May 1933). PP 64- 65. "Variétés," CinquiBme ann6e, No. 4 (February 21, 1931), p. 61. 391 "Variétés," Neuvigme ann6e, No. 4 (April 1935), p. 61. "Vari6t6s: les plantations/indigenes de Caf6 au Ruanda-Urundi," Dixieme annee, No. 7 (July 1936), p. 110. "Les Zones de Protection du Caf6’en-Ruanda-Urundi," Septieme ann6e, No. 6 (May 1933), p. 66. Annuaire official du MinistEre des Colonies (de Belgique). Brussels: A. Lesigne, 1921-1959. Becquet, A. "Moyens mis en oeuvre et les r6sultats obtenus dans la lutte contre la famine au Ruanda," Journ6es d' Agronomie coloniale, (June 23-24,1933), pp. 39- 42. Bourgeois, R. Banyarwanda et Burundi. L'6yolution du contrat de bail a cheptel au Ruanda-Urundi. Brussels: ARSG, 1958. d'Arianoff, A. Histoire des Bagesera: souverains du Gisaku. Brussels: I.R.C.B., tome XXIV, fasc. 3, 1952. Dubois, B. "La politique 6conomique coloniale, 1932-1934," Bulletin l'Institut des Sciences economiques, Sixiéme ann6e, No. 2 (February 1935), pp. 129-143. Dufays, Felix. Pages d'epogée africaine. Ixelles: Weverbergh, 1928. Gourou, Pierre. La Densit6 de la Population au Ruanda: esquisse d' une Etude Géographique. Brussels: /Institut Royal Colonial belge, Section des Scienceg Naturelles et Medicales, m6moire, Tome XXI, fasc. §/, 1952. . Notice de la Carte de la Densit6 de la Population au Congo belge et au Ruanda-Urundi. Brussels: Institut Royal Colonial Belge, Atlas Géheral du Congo 1951. Gouvernement belge, MinistEre des Colonies: Major Declerk. "Rapport d' ensemble sur la situation de la R6sidence du Ruanda_ et sur 1' activit6 de 1' Administration." in. d_/. Rapport sur l'Administration belge des territoires occupés d6 l'Est Africain Allemand. Brussels: Imprimerie E. Guyst, S. A., 1921. 392 Rapport sur l'Administration belge du Ruanda et de l'Urundi, 1921-1923. Brussels: Goemaere, 1922-1924. Rapport present6 par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société des Nations au sujet de l'Administration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant l'Année, 1924. GenEve: Société des Nations, 1925. Rapportpresent6 par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Soci6t6 des Nations au sujet de l'Administration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant l'Ann6e, 1925-1926. Brussels: F. Van Gompel, Imprimeur-Editeur, 1926-1927. Chambre des Representants, Session de 1923-1924. Rapport sur l'Administration Belge du Ruanda-Urundi presente aux Chambres. Brussels: F. Van Gompel, Imprimeur--Editeur, 1924. Rapport presenté'par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Societe des Nations au Sujet de l'Administration du Ruanda—Urundi pendant l'Année, 1927-1932. Brussels: Etablissements Emile Bruylant, 1928-1933. Rapport present6'par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Société des Nations au Sujet de l'Administration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant 1'Ann6e, 1933. Brussels: Imprimerie E. Guyot, S. A., 1934. Rapport present6 par 1e Gouvernement Belge au Conseil de la Soci6t6 des Nations au Sujet de l'Administration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant 1'Ann6é, 1934-1946. Brussels: Etablissements Generaux d‘Imprimerie, 1935-1948. Rapport soumis par le Gouvernement Belge 3'1'Assemblée Générale des Nations Unies au Sujet de l'Administration du Ruanda-Urundi pendant l'Année, 1947-49. Brussels: Etablissements Géhéraux d'Imprimerie, 1948-1950. Service des Territoires des Colonies; Dossier AE/ll, No. 1847, portefeuille 3288X. ln.d;/. Kagame, Alexis. Le Codes des Institutions politiques du Rwanda Precolonial. Brussels: Editions du Marais, 1952. Lefebrve, Jacques. Structures 6conomiques du Congo Belge et du Ruanda-Urundi. Brussels: Edition de Treurenberg, 1955. 393 Leurquin, Philippe. "Les limites physiques de 1e production de Subsistence," Bulletin de 1' Institut de Recherche 6conomiques et soc1a1es (Universit6 de Louvain), XXIII, No. 2 (1957). Pp. 48- 66. Molitor, G. "L' Introduction et le D6veloppement de la Culture du Caf6ier Arabica chez les Indigene du Ruanda-Urundi," Le Materiel Colonial A. S. B. L., 27 6me Ann6e, No. 6 (March 1937), pp. 154- 180. Pages, Albert. "Un Royaume Hamit6 au centre de l‘Afrique," IRCM (Brussels), I (1933), pp. 195-232. Ryckmans, Pierre. La Politique Coloniale. Brussels: Les Edition Rex, 1934. . "Une Page d' Histoire Coloniale: 1' Occupation Allemande dans 1' Urundi," IRCB (Brussels), XXIX "Tribal Traditions Hinder Progress in Ruanda-Urundi," Bulletin Nations Unies XVI, No. 7 (April 1954), pp. 267-269. Vansina, Jan. L'6volution du royaume Rwanda des Origines 3 1900. Brussels: Academie Royale des Sciences d'Outre-Mer, 1962. H. AFRICAN ARCHIVES, BRUSSELS, BELGIUM Carton Agri (106), Dossier 47, FEDECAME: Accord de Mexico, 1957, 4 eme Direction G6n6ra1, Agriculture, For6ts, Elevage, Colonisation, l ere Direction a FEDECAME. Crédit accordes en faveur de la production du Caf6. in. d_/. (109), Dossier 54--Caf6, Groupe d'Etude du Caf6 5' Washington, 1959: International Bank of Reconstruc- tion and Development, L. Baranysi, History of Commodity Agreements (Economic Staff Report, 1959). (110), Dossier 59, Ministere du Congo belge et du Ruanda-Urundi, Accord International du Congo, Washington: 4 eme Direction G6n6rale, 3 Eme Direction a M. 1e Ministre du Commerce Extérieur. Brussels, July 31,1959. (340), Dossier 207, Ministere des Colonies, Note pour la 6 eme Directeur G6n6rale. Brussels, February 17, 1932. ‘ -—-~' -1... 1r _:r 394 Carton Agri (341), No. 417, T616gramme d' Etat regu du Gouverneur G6n6ral Ryckmans. Costermansville, No. 12, November 8,1935. , , No. 418, D6peches du Congo Belge: Incopresse, Service Colonial Belga, D6péche No. 1350, T. S. F. Anvers, November 23,1935. , , No. 418, Annexe, Depeches du Con o Belge, Incopresse, Service Colonial Belga, Dep che No. 351, T. S. F., Heure L60, No. 314. Anvers, November 23, 1935. , , No. 425, Annexe, M. Ren6.Hebette 3 Monsieur 1e Directeur G6n6ra1. Brussels, January 14, 1936. , , No. 426, Association des Planteurs de Caf6 du Congo 3 Monsieur 1e Ministre des Colonies. Anvers, December 24, 1935. , , No. 428, Ministre des Colonies a M. 1e Gouverneur G6n6ral a Leopoldville. Brussels, February IL 1936. , , No. 436, Annexe, Association des Planteur de Cafe du Congo 3 Monsieur E. Rubbens, Ministre des Colonies. Anvers, March 12, 1936. , , No. 436,5 eme Direction G6n6rale, Pour 1e Ministre, 1e Directeur, Chef de Service 3 Monsieur 1e President de 1' APCC. Brussels, March 23,1936. , , No. 439, Incopresse. Costermansville, March 23, 1936. , , No. 452, S‘Eme Direction G6h6ra1e, Note pour 1e Ministre. Brussels, September 2, 1936. , , No. 454, 5 6me Direction 66n6ra1e, Note pour 1e Ministre. Brussels, September 2, 1936. , , No. 458, Ministere des Colonies, 5 eme Direction G6n6ra1, Note pour la 4 eme Direction G6n6rale. Brussels, December 4, 1936. , , No. 484, Incopresse, Les D6bouch6s pour 1e Caf6 Belge au Kenya, Anvers, 9 octobre 1937. Costermansville, October 9, 1937. , , No. 512, T616gramme d'Etat, Ubelco au Ministére des Cclonies. Costermansville, March 1938. 395 Carton Agri (341), No. 513,5 eme Direction G6n6ra1, Note pour le Ministre, 1e Secretaire G6n6ral a Monsieur 1e Gouverneur du Ruanda-Urundi, Usumbura. Brussels, March 18, 1938. , _, No. 514, Ministere des Colonies, 4 eme D1rection G6n6rale, 3 eme Direction, projet t616— gramme, Ubelco, Costermansville. Brussels, March 17, 1938. , _, No. 525, T616gramme d' Etat exp6di6 au Gouverneur G6n6ral, Leopoldville, No. 84. Brussels, April 7,1938. , , No. 526,4 eme Direction G6n6rale, 3 6me D1rection a Gouverneur G6n6ral, Leopoldville. Brussels, April 11,1938. , , No. 527, Annexe II, S'Bme Direction G6n6rale, Note pour Monsieur 1e Ministre. Brussels, (1938). , No. 527, Conseil Colonial sur un projet d6cret limitant temporairement les plantations de Caf6 au Congo Belge et au Ruanda-Urundi (with 3 Annexes). Brussels, July 8, 1938. , , No. 52L Annexe I, Projet de d6cret sur la limitation temporaire des plantations de caf6 au Congo Belge et au Ruanda-Urundi (1938). W, No. 528, Annexe III, Ubelco a M. Rubbens, M1n1stere des Colonies. Costermansville, March 12, 1938. , No. 528, Limitation des Plantations de Caf6, No. 528/10, 4 6me Direction 66n6rale, 3 6me Direction, Note pour M. 1e Ministre (with annexe). Brussels, March 22, 1938. , No. 528, Limitation des Plantations de Caf6, No. 528/12, Prescobel a Brussels, Information coloniale. Costermansville, Tuesday, July 14, 1938. , No. 528, Limitation des Plantations de Caf6, No. 528/10, Annexe, Rapport: Subvention de 6,000,000 de la Metropole. (1938). , , No. 528/12, UPCC a Monsieur Van den Abeele, Directeur G6n6ral au Ministere des Colonies (with 3 Annexes). Brussels, April 23,1938. — 396 Carton Agri (341), No. 547, Rapport pour M. 1e Ministre. May 30, 1938. Carton Agri (342), Dossier Caf6s C/I, R6glementation, Limitation des Plantations de Caféiers Anciens Dossiers: C/I/3, du MinistEre des Colonies, S'Eme Direction G6n6ral'3 M. 1e Gouverneur G6n6ral 3' Leopoldville (with annexes). Brussels, March 20, 1946. : C/I/S, 5 eme Direction G6n6rale, 1e Directeur Géneral, Note pour M. 1e Ministre des Colonies (with annexes). Brussels, October 8, 1946. , : C/I/8, S‘Eme Direction G6n6rale S'M. 1e Gouverneur G6n6ral E Leopoldville (with annexes). Brussels, October 16, 1946. : C/I/9, Gouvernement G6n6ral, Agriculture et Colonisation, Congo Belge a M. le Ministre des Colonies (with annexes). Leopoldville, October 29, 1946. , _, Dossier Caf6 C/II, R6glemenation, C/II/4: Union des Planteurs de Caf6 du Congo Belgea Monsieur Staner, Directeur au Ministere des Colonies. Brussels, February 9, 1945. , Dossier, Limitation des Plantations de Caf6, No. 528, Annexe III, Union Belge des Colonies au Kivu (Ubelco) a M. Rubbens, Ministre des Colonies. Costermansville, March 12, 1938. , , No. 528, Annexe II, Gouvernement G6n6ral Affaires Economique Congo Belge a M. le Ministre des Colonies. Leopoldville, March 25, 1938. , No. 528, Annexe I, Service de 1' Agriculture, Territoire Ruanda-Urundi a Monsieur le President de 1' Union Belge des Colons du Kivu a Costermansville. Usumbura, March 30, 1938. , , No. 528 Service de l'Agriculture, Territoire Ruanda-Urundi a Monsieur 1e Gouverneur G6n6ral du Congo Belge E'Leo-Kalina (with 3 annexes). Usumbura, March 30, 1938. , , No. 528/12, Gouvernement G6n6ral Affaires Economiques Congo Belge a M. le Ministre des Colonies a Brussels. Leopoldville, April 22,1938. 397 Carton Agri (342), Dossier LCaf6, 1935-19327, No. 547, Rapport pour M. le Ministre. Brussels, May 30, 1938. , , No. 591, Soci6t6 Anonyme de Cultures au Congo Belge a M. 1e Ministre des Colonies. Brussels, February 22,1939. , , No. 593, Annexe, 5 6me Direction G6n6rale, Note pour la 4 6me Direction G6n6rale. Brussels, March 3, 1939. , _, No. 593, 4 eme Direction G6n6rale, 3 eme Direction, Note pour la 5 eme Direction Générale (with annexe). Brussels, March 7,1939. _, Dossier No. 528- 2 eme, Limitation des Planta- t1ons de Caf6, No. 528/40,1a R6union du 19 mai 1939, ll heures, du U. P. P. U. Brussels, May 22,1939. , , No. 528/41, S'éme Direction G6n6rale, Note pour M. 1e Ministére. Brussels, May 26, 1939. , , No. 528/42, Annexe, Ren6 Brasseur a la Union Professionnelle, des Producteurs de Cafe du Congo Belge. Brussels, June 5, 1939. , No. 528/44, Pour 1e MinistEre 1e Secr6taire Généra1,5 6me Direction G6n6rale, S‘M. 1e President de 1' Union Professionnelle des Producteurs de Caf6 du Congo Belge et du Ruanda-Urundi. Brussels, June 20, 1939. , , No. 528/45, 5 eme Direction G6n6rale, Pour le Min1stere, 1e Secr6taire G6n6ral a M. Godding, Administrateur D6l6gu6 de la Soci6t6 de Culture, au Congo Belge a Brussels. Brussels, June 24,1939. , F, No. 528/47, Campagnie de l'Ue16 a M. le D1recteur G§h6rale du Service d'Agriculture au Ministere des Colonies (with annexes). Kurukwata, par Aba, July 17,1939. , ,_Uo. 528/48, Union des Producteurs de Caf6 Belge a M. le MinistEre des Colonies. Brussels, August 3, 1939. , , No. 528/49, Union des Producteurs de Caf6 du Congo Belge S'Monsieur le MinistEre des Colonies. Brussels, September 8, 1939. 398 Carton Agri (342), No. 528/51, telegramme regu, adressé’au Ministre des Colonies de 1' Unake a Costermansville (with 3 annexes). Costermansville, November 21, 1939. , , No. 528/51, Annexe III, 5 Ema Direction Ganeral, Pour le Ministre, 1e Secretaire General a M. le Gouverneur General, Leopoldville. Leopoldville, November 27, 1939. , , No. 528/51, Annexe II, télécramme regu de Costermansville de l'Ubelco. Costermansville, December 13, 1939. , , No. 528/51, Annexe I, télééramme d'Etat, regu du Gouverneur Général Ryckmans. Leopoldville, No. 34, December 15, 1939. , No. 528/53, S'Bme Direction Generale, Note pour M. le Ministre, par M. Van den Abeele. Brussels, November 25, 1939. , , Dossier No. 528, C/I/I, Anciens Dossiers, No. 528/60, R. Godding E'M. le Ministre des Colonies (with annexe). Brussels, March 28, 1940. , , No. 528/61, s'ame Direction, Note pour M. 1e Ministre. Brussels, April 3, 1940. , , Dossier Caf6 C/II, Reglementation: C/II/4, Union des Producteurs de Café du Congo Belge‘a Monsieur Staner. Brussels, February 9, 1945. , No. B/I/23--OCIRU, Note pour M. 1e Gouverneur General, Office du Café Indigene du Ruanda-Urundi et Liberté Commerciale, du President 0. P. A., G. Sladden. Leopoldville, January 9, 1946. , , No. B/I/28--OCIRU, du Ministere des Colonies, 5 eme Direction Generale, 1e Directeur General, Note pour M. 1e Ministre. Brussels, February 28,1946. Carton Agri/ (343), 1936--Kenya, Dossier E, Caf6 Divers: Marches; Politique Café Robusta, etc.; E- l, Ministére des Colonies, 4 Eme Direction a M. le President de l'Association des Planteurs de Cafe du Congo (with one attachment and Appendix "A"--transport). Brussels, January 13, 1936. , , 1937--Dossier E-gbas, Pret Planteurs Caf6 Kivu, No. /428/9, Ministere des Colonies, 4 eme Direction Generale, 2 eme Direction, Note pour M. 12 Directeur Général du Service de l'Agriculture. Brussels, April 14, 1937. "5" . 113-qr— 399 Carton Agri (343), No. 428/10, No. 7526, Comit6 National du Kivu a M. le Ministre. Brussels, March 23, 1937. , , No. 428/12, Gouvernement G6n6rale Affaires Economiques a M. le Ministre des Colonies (with annexes). Leopoldville, July 16,1937. , N2. 428/ll, Societ6 Cooperative des Planteurs du K1vu a Monsieur le Ministre. Costermansville, September 10,1937. , , l938--Kenya: E- 1, Annexes, Coffee Trade Association of Kenya a le Consulat General a Nairobi. Nairobi, August 7,1938. , , l939--Dossier Ejgbas, Pret Planteurs Caf6 Kivu, No. 428/37, Comite National du Kivu a M. 1e Ministre. Brussels, February 7,1939. , , l939--Dossier E, Caf6 Divers; Marchés, Politique Caf6 Robusta, etc.: Dossier E-2, No. 608, 5 eme Direction G6n6rale, 3 eme Direction, Inspecteur Gén6ral ff. de Directeur G6n6ral. Brussels, July 1, 1939. , , No. 608/3, Annexe, Soci6t6 Anonyme de Cultures au Congo Belge a M. Van den Abeele, Directeur G6n6rale au Ministre des Colonies. Brussels, July 4,1939. , No. 608/5, t616gramme, 4 eme Direction Générale, 3‘Bme Direction du Gouverneur Gén6ral a Leopoldville. Brussels, July 12,1939. , , No. 608/6, 4 6me Direction Gén6rale, 3 6me D1rection a M. le President de 1' Union des P. C. C. Brussels, July 17,1939. , _, l940--Dossier H, Caf6'; Taxes Diverses H/6 5 eme Direction G6n6rale, Note pour la 3 6me Direction G6n6rale. Brussels, January 2,1940. , , No. 643/1, T616 egramme regu adress6 au Ministre des Colonies. Costermansville, January 28,1940. , _, No. 643/2, Ministere des Colonies, S'éme Direction Générale, Note pour la 4 eme Direction G6n6rale. Brussels, January 31,1940. , , No. 643/4, T616§ramme regu de la Chambre de Commerce de Costermansville a Ministere des Colonies. Costermansville, February L 1940. 400 Carton Agri (343), No. 643/6, 4 6me Direction G6n6rale, B‘Eme Direction, Note pour M. 1e Ministre. Brussels, February 13, 1940. , , No. 643/7, 5‘6me Direction G6n6rale, Note pour M. 1e Ministre. Brussels, March 1, 1940. , , No. 643/10, 5 6me Direction 66n6rale, Note pour M. 1e Ministre, 1e Procgs-verbal de la R6union du 28 mars 1940 de la sous-Commission Economique Interministerielle. Brussels, April 3, 1940. , , 4 6me Direction G6n6rale, 1 Ere Direction, Note pour M. le Ministre. Brussels, April 2, 1940. , , Comptoir des Cafés Victor de Hae a‘M. Van den Abeele, au Ministere des Colonies, Brussels. Antwerp, April 12, 1940. , , l940--Dossier E, Caf6'Divers, Dossier E-3, Mévente des Arabicas, Ministére des Colonies, Note pour la 4 6me Direction G6n6rale. Brussels, n.d.