1,. 12‘ OI‘!‘ 303 a , iiiiiiiiiiii This is to certify that the dissertation entitled PUBLIC POLICY CHANGES AND THE VIABILITY OF LOCAL COLLECTIVE BARGAINING RELATIONSHIPS ACROSS MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES DURING THE 19805 presented by MATTHEW M . BO DAH has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Socia] Sciences W Major professor DateW7I’/m‘ I MSU it an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0- 12771 IF‘II LIBRARY Michigan State Unlverslty PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES Mum on or before date duo. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE MSUIsMAmmdh‘ ' '1 "r, A ',2.....'2.‘.1... .~ W “"“3 0‘ It‘ .‘1 L‘“ V. mic FQLICY CHANGES AND THE VIABILITY OF mean BARGAINING RELATIONSHIPS ACROSS WBING INDUSTRIES DURING THE 19808 By Matthew M. Bodah ‘z study "31'. WNEWHA ad" in nga-.: . m flrtab ~'. tflv 5E: “mum"; " ' A W a!" t‘ ;A DISSERTATION . to bark} I N, 0: “ha :5 Submitted t0 5 w‘, Michigan State University . . .; rfglfillmant of the requirements s..- for the degree of tho pol!" . :3! A DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY .{Ol‘y (51.11%) zgf Labor and InduStrial Relations 1.: - ' 0991133 1' I M 5"». 1996 Of DI’PSQV‘Jn' . 5 '.'., 1+“ 5, )nCIudinQ van 1.32%; ea (stream: L319 “ions. lhp'u Swat. Mutton; of the Augl‘ir;-- :. (that-[1.2.5 L5 '.’.- exazuue firm and ABSTRACT PUBLIC POLICY CHANGES AND THE VIABILITY OF LOCAL COLLECTIVE BARGAINING RELATIONSHIPS ACROSS MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES DURING THE 19808 BY Matthew M. Bodah In this study the author examines the impact of public policy changes under the National Labor Relations Act during the 1980s on local collective bargaining relationships in fourteen.manufacturing industries. The areas of policy studied relate to a model of local collective bargaining unit disappearance, specifically: an employer’s duty to bargain over capital decisions, union security, and standards of behavior in decertification elections. Political and institutional changes at the National Labor Relations Board, which preceded the policy changes, are also examined. A An event history analysis using a pooled time—series regression model is applied to data across the fourteen industries measured in four waves of observations between the mid- 19708 and late- IOOOS. The purpose of the regression analysis is to examine the stability of a model including variables representing firm ‘ .9Q‘|‘-‘ :Qia'.<‘ failures, plant relocations, input substitution, and decertification. The main hypothesis of the study is that bargaining unit disappearances will be linked to industry economic distress early in the period, but more closely associated with relocations, input substitutions, and decertification elections later in the period as mid-19805 policy changes take hold. Results nay assist in resolving the debate between those who argue that union decline is largely the result of structural economic changes and those who point instead to increasingly unfavorable public policy. Qualitative findings indicate that indeed there were sharp reversals in most of the salient policy areas following the Reagan administration’s ideological reordering of the National Labor Relations Board in 1983. The quantitative findings show that firm failure rates across industries were a strong significant predictor of bargaining unit disappearances for the entire period, for the period following 1980, but not for the period following 1983. After 1983, the evidence suggests that disappearances may actually have been more typical in relatively healthy industries, where capital investments and changes in the cross—state distribution of firms were occuring. The lack of nwre recent data makes it difficult to arrive at more definite conclusions. The study ends with a discussion of the unsettled question of the appropriate role of the federal government in the development of labor relations policy. AC KNOWLEDG EMENTS I would like to thank everyone who assisted me in the completion of this dissertation. First, my thanks go to my committee: Richard Block, Joel Cutcher—Gershenfeld, Edilberto Montemayor, Lisa Fine, and Harry Perlstadt. But, indeed, I thank everyone at Michigan State: the faculty and staff of the School of Labor and Industrial Relations, friends and acquaintances in the Departments of Sociology and History, and particularly my colleagues in the doctoral program, especially my office mates Pat McHugh and Victor Nichol. I also owe a large debt of gratitude to my current colleagues at the University of Rhode Island who have supported me throughout this endeavor: Ted Schmidt, Mary Pinch, Scott Molloy, Carl Gersuny, Larry Rothstein, Mark Grossman, Laura Beauvais, Suzanne Taylor, and Richard McIntyre, to name just a few. Further, I must acknowledge the Support of my family: my parents William and Teresa, my sister Paula, and my brothers Henry and Timothy. Rinally, I thank Theres for her kindness, patience, and understanding. TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES CHAPTER I. INTRODUCTION AND OVERVIEW INTRODUCTION THE IMPORTANCE OF LOCAL COLLECTIVE BARGAINING RELATIONSHIPS THE IMPORTANCE OF LAW AND PUBLIC POLICY A FRAMEWORK FOR STUDYING THE DISAPPEARANCE OF LOCAL RELATIONSHIPS RESEARCH OBJECTIVE THE CHAPTERS CHAPTER II. LITERATURE REVIEW INTRODUCTION . UNION GROWTH AND DECLINE ECONOMIC EXPLANATIONS POLICY EXPLANATIONS INTERNATIONAL AND COMPARATIVE RESEARCH . DOMESTIC RESEARCH BRIDGING THE LITERATURE CHAPTER III. INSTITUTIONAL CHANGES INTRODUCTION A FORESHADOWING OF CONFLICT OPEN CONFLICT AT THE BOARD IMPACT OF THE NEW BOARD CONCLUSIONS CHAPTER IV. DOCTRINAL CHANGES INTRODUCTION . THE DUTY TO BARGAIN IN GOOD FAITH AN EMPLOYER’ S DUTY TO BARGAIN OVER DECISIONS AFFECTING THE BARGAINING UNIT MOVING WORK DURING THE LIFE OF AN AGREEMENT . . THE LOSS OF CERTIFICATION . . QUESTIONS OF MAJORITY SUPPORT UNION DISCIPLINE ii H \Infi 12 18 20 20 20 22 28 28 3O 34 37 37 37 50 59 69 71 71 72 76 93 97 97 101 STANDARDS OF CONDUCT DURING DECERTIFICATION ELECTIONS . . . . . . . . 105 CONCLUSIONS . . . . 101 CHAPTER V. INDEPENDENT VARIABLES AND HYPOTHESES . 112 INTRODUCTION . . . 112 BUSINESS DECISIONS AFFECTING THE BARGAINING UNIT . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113 PLANT CLOSINGS . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113 PLANT RELOCATIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . 122 SUBCONTRACTING . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125 TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE . . . . . . . . . . 129 LOSS OF CERTIFICATION . . . . . . . . . . . . 132 SUMMARY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134 HYPOTHESES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135 CONCLUSIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144 CHAPTER VI. DATA AND METHODS . . . . . . . . . . . 147 INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147 THE SAMPLE . . . . . . . 147 CALCULATION OF THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE: PANEL ATTRITION . . . . . . . . . . . . 152 PROBLEMS WITH AGGREGATION'. ECOLOGICAL FALLACY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158 THE LONGITUDINAL METHOD: AN EVENT HISTORY DESIGN . . . 161 PROBLEMS: INTERACTION AND MULTICOLLINEARITY . 164 FORMULAE . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165 MODEL 1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165 MODELS 2 THROUGH 4 . . . . . . . . . . . 166 MODELS 5 THROUGH 7 . . . . . . . . . . . 167 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS . . . . . . . . . . . . 168 VARIABLES . . . . . . . . . . . . 169 DISAPPEARANCE RATE . . . . . . . . . 169 FIRM FAILURE RATE . . . 171 CHANGE IN CROSS- STATE DISTRIBUTION . 172 RATE OF GROWTH IN NEW CAPITAL EXPENDITURES . . . . . 173 ANNUAL RATE OF CHANGE IN SMALL ESTABLISHMENTS . . . . . . . . 174 DECERTIFICATION ELECTIONS . . . . 175 AVERAGE ANNUAL ESTABLISHMENT CHANGE 176 AVERAGE ANNUAL CHANGE IN PRODUCTION WORKER EMPLOYMENT . . . . 178 CAPITAL INTENSITY . . . . . . . 179 UNION PENETRATION RATES . . . . . . 180 INDUSTRIES . . . . . . . . 181 SIC 20, FOOD PRODUCTS . . . . . . . 182 SIC 22, TEXTILES . . . . . . . . . . 183 SIC 24, LUMBER . . . . . . . . . . . 184 iii SIC 25, FURNITURE . . . . . . . . . 185 SIC 26, PAPER . . . . . . . . . . . 186 SIC 28, CHEMICALS . . . . . . . . . 187 SIC 29, PETROLEUM . . . . . . . . . 188 SIC 30, RUBBER . . . . . . 189 SIC 32, STONE, GLASS, AND CLAY . . . 190 SIC 33, PRIMARY METALS . . . . . . . 191 SIC 34, FABRICATED METALS . . . . . 192 SIC 35, MACHINERY . . . . . . . 193 SIC 36, ELECTRICAL EQUIPMENT . . . . 194 SIC 37, TRANSPORTATION EQUIPMENT . . 195 SUMMARY . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 196 CHAPTER VII. RESULTS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 198 INTRODUCTION . . . . . . 198 TREND IN LOCAL BARGAINING RELATIONSHIP DISAPPEARANCE . . . . . . . . . . . . . 200 ZERO- ORDER CORRELATIONS . . . . . . . . . . . 203 REGRESSION MODELS . . . . . . . . . . . . . 208 CONSTANT TIME MODEL . . . . . . . . . . . 208 TIME VARYING MODEL . . . . . . . . . . . 211 ALTERNATIVE MODELS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 220 NON- LAGGED MODEL . . . . . . . . . . 220 A MORE PARSIMONIOUS MODEL . . . . . . . . 223 CONCLUSIONS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228 CHAPTER VIII. CONCLUSIONS AND DISCUSSION . . . . . 233 INTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 233 DISCUSSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 238 LIST OF REFERENCES . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 248 L iv LI ST OF TABLES Table 6.1. Sample characteristics, selected industries, 1977 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152 Table 6.2. Disappearance rate, by industry, 3—year periods, 1977—1990 . . . . . . . . . . 169 Table 6.3. Firm failure rate, per 10,000 firms, by industry, 3—year periods, 1974—1986 . . . . 172 Table 6.4. Percentage point change in distribution of establishments across states, by industry, 3-year periods, 1974-1986 . . . . . . . . . . 173 Table 6.5. Average annual rate of change in new capital expenditures, by industry, 3—year periods, 1974-1986 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174 Table 6.6. Average annual rate of growth in the percentage of establishments with fewer than 100 employees, by industry, 3—year periods, 1974—1986 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175 Table 6. 7. Annual average decertification elections per 10, 000 bargaining units, by industry, 3—year periods, 1974- 1986 . . . . . . . 176 Table 6.8. Percentage change in the number of establishments, by industry, 3—year periods, 1974—1986 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 178 Table 6.9. Annual average percentage change in the number of production workers, by industry, 3-year periods, 1974-1986 . . . . . . . . . . 179 Table 6 10. Percentage of assets invested in capital equipment, by industry, 3—year periods, 1974- 1986 . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180 ” Table 6.11. Average union penetration rates, by industry, 3—year periods, 1974-1986 . . . . 181 Table 6.12. SIC 20. Food Products . . . . . . . . 183 Table 6.13. SIC 22. Textiles . . . . . . . . . . 184 Table 6.14. SIC 24. Lumber . . . . . . . . . . . 185 Table 6.15. SIC 25. Furniture . . . . . . . . . . 186 Table 6.16. SIC 26. Paper . . . . . . . . . . . . 187 Table 6.17. SIC 28. Chemicals . . . . . . . . . . 188 Table 6.18. SIC 29. Petroleum . . . . . . . . . . 189 Table 6.19. SIC 30. Rubber . . . . . . . . . . . 190 Table 6.20. SIC 32. Stone, Glass, and Clay . . . 191 Table 6.21. SIC 33. Primary Metals . . . . . . . 192 Table 6.22. SIC 34. Fabricated Metals . . . . . . 193 Table 6.23. SIC 35. Machinery . . . . . . . . . . 194 Table 6.24. SIC 36. Electrical Equipment . . . . 195 Table 6.25. SIC 37. Transportation Equipment . . 196 Table 7.1. Hypotheses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 199 Table 7.2. Production worker employment, selected manufacturing industries, 1975, 1980, 1985, 1990, in thousands 202 Table 7.3. Zero—order correlations . . . . . . . . 205 Table 7.4. Standardized regression coefficients, lagged model, t—values in parentheses, N=56 . 209 Table 7.5. Standardized regression coefficients with period effects, lagged model, t-values in parentheses, N=56 . . . . . . . . 212 Table 7.6. Standardized regression coefficients with period effects and cross—products, lagged model, t—values in parentheses, N=56 . . 217 vi Table 7.7. Standardized regression coefficients, alternative models, t-values in parentheses, N:56 . . . . . . Table 7.8. Standardized regression coefficients, lagged reduced model, t—values in parentheses, N:56 Table 7.9. Standardized regression coefficients, lagged reduced model with period effects, t—values in parentheses, N:56 Table 7.10. Standardized regression coefficients, lagged reduced model with period effects and cross-products, t—values in parentheses, N:56 222 224 226 228 Chapter I. Introduction and Overview. A. Introduction. Perhaps the most widely—reported fact concerning American industrial relations during the 1980s was the sharp decrease in the number of individuals belonging to labor unions or covered by collective bargaining agreements.1 From 1980 to 1990, the percent of workers belonging to unions decreased from 23 to 16. In manufacturing alone, the number declined from 36 to 22 percent. Although a downward trend had started in the mid-19505, the rate of decline accelerated quickly after 1980. (Kokkeneleberg and Sockell, 1985; Curme, Hirsch, MacPherson, 1990; Hirsch and MacPherson, 1993). The reasons for the recent decline in unionism and for the dynamics of union growth and decline more generally have been examined by a number of scholars (see the literature reviews of Block and Premack, 1983; Chiason and Rose, 1991; Fiorito, Gallagher, and Greer, 1986; and Wheeler and McLendon, . #h m” ‘ Not all workers who are covered by collective agreements choose to join the unions representing them. During the 19803, coverage tended to exceed membership by approximately two percentage points (Curme, Hirsch and Macpherson, 1990) 2 1991). Several leading theories emerge from this literature.2 And although a number of scholars have attempted to achieve a synthesis of thought (Kochan, Katz, and McKersie, 1986; Block, 1990), there remains some divergence between those who emphasize public policy explanations and those who focus instead on more purely economic and market-driven factors. Put in terns of an older and broader social—scientific debate, the two groups represent, respectively, those favoring historical and non—historical points—of—view (see Stepina and Fiorito, 1986, for a similar c1assification)3 In recent times, the principal focus of the former group has been the growing opposition to unions by employers during in the past couple of decades and the failure of public officials to respond (Dickens, 1983; Dickens and Leonard, 1985; Freeman, 1985, 1988; Freeman and Medoff, 1984; Weiler, 1983, 1990). ’ This point will be developed further in Chapter 2. ’ Stepina and Fiorito use the terms “saturationists” and I'historians." But in a footnote (1986, p. 248, note 1) they explain: The term ’saturationist’ (first popularized by Bell (1953)) has probably outlived its usefulness. It might be more meaningful to distinguished between ’modelers’ and ’historians’ or qualitative versus quantitative approaches. For the debate between historicists and non-historicists in the social sciences, see Karl Popper (1957) for a classic treatment and Theda Skocpol (1984) for a more recent examination. _ ./ 3 Indeed, some have argued that the posture of public officials and the outcomes of public policy, particularly in the mid- 19805, reflect government complicity with employer opposition (Bluestone and. Bluestone, 1992; Gould, 1986, 1993). The latter group, the economic theorists, submit that mainly market and concomitant structural—economic changes are responsible for union decline, particularly the shift of jobs away from heavy manufacturing, where most union members were found, to light manufacturing and service (Jones, 1992; LaLonde and Meltzer, 1991; Sheflin, Troy and Koeller, 1981; Troy, 1969, 1990). The debate between these schools is fascinating, and, at times, heated.‘ A major problem, however, is that the two sides often talk past each other by focusing their arguments on different phenomena. The policy theorists focus most frequently on the inability of unions to gain new members, with their most powerful arguments concerning employer ~opposition to union organizing drives and initial contracts (Cooke, 1985; Dickens, 1983; Weiler, 1983; Freeman, 1989, 1989a, 1989b), while the economic theorists find their most persuasive case in the decline of unionization in areas of previous strength (Jones, 1992; Troy, 1969, 1990). Perhaps ‘ The best examples are Troy’s (1990) sharp (at times personal) attack on Freeman and the debate between Weiler and LaLonde and Meltzer (1991). m. 4 lack of growth and decline require two separate theoretical conceptualizations? In this research, I will attempt to bridge these two bodies of knowledge by borrowing from both schools. Typical of the recent public policy work, I will focus heavily on doctrinal and institutional changes that were, I believe, unfavorable to collective bargaining and damaging to labor unions. But instead of walking the well—trod path of those who have examined union organizing, I will focus, instead, on threats to the viability of existing local collective bargaining relationships.5 In doing so, I look at a phenomenon more central the arguments of the economic theorists. B. The importance of local collective bargaining relationships. One characteristic of the union decline literature is that, invariably, empirical studies use some measure of the number of individuals belonging to unions as the dependent variable. But as Block and Premack (1983, p. 45) note: There is a weakness common to all studies that use change in union membership as the dependent variable. This limitation is based on the fact that a substantial percentage of union members at any time made no explicit choice to join their union; rather they simply took ’ Changing standards for union elections are not ignored completely since they are relevant in the discussion of union decertification. W 5 a job in a firm that was already unionized and had a union security agreement. In short, changes in the number of union members probably tell us more about labor markets than about industrial ~re1ations activity. It is analogous to the problem, cited by Buss and Redburn (1987), of using unemployment statistics to make statements about the impact of plant closings on communities. Rather, the essential building blocks of the American industrial relations system——and one factor that makes the American system somewhat exceptional—~are local, plant-level, union—employer relationships (Bok and Dunlop, 1970; Kochan, 1980). In this study, I will depart from the previous practice of studying membership levels, and use pre— existing local collective bargaining relationships as the unit of analysis. The American system of industrial relations is almost completely dependent upon these local relationships. Employers (and hence employees) who are unionized are part of the system, non—union employers (and hence employees) are not. This highly decentralized system stands in rather sharp contrast to many other industrial relations systems, particularly those of Western Europe, which rely heavily on centralized institutions and bargaining structures, particularly union and employer associations (Bamber and Lansbury, 1987; Dunlop and Galenson, 1978). In most other 6 nations, once deals are struck between employers and unions at the national, industrial, or regional levels, terms of employment are enforced on all employers, regardless of whether employees at a particular location have selected affiliation 'with any particular labor organization. The terms nunion" and "non—union" employer are largely meaningless. In the United States, these terms are far from meaningless and are essential to who is and who is not part of the industrial relations system. Although there are also centralized bargaining mechanisms in this country——though many fewer than there used to be (Katz, 1993)-—they differ from1 European structures in that agreements entered into between employer and union associations cannot be enforced at workplaces where employees have not chosen union representation.‘ This is not to deny the spillover effects of unionism, nor the impact of unions on public policy more generally (Freeman and Medoff, 1984; Delaney, Master, and Schwochau, 1990; Lepo, 1992). However, only unionized workplaces are formal components of the industrial relations system. ‘ When wages are subject to regulation by prevailing wage laws, e.g. Davis-Bacon and Walsh—Healey, the American system functions somewhat like the European. Wage and Hour officials frequently rely on union labor agreements to set the prevailing wage rate, which then must be paid by all employers. 7 An additional point is that an examination of relationships is likely to tell us more about employer intentions than would an examination of membership levels. If union workers are laid-off from an establishment, the size of the labor movement is reduced. But if the employer continues to bargain in good faith with the representative of the remaining employees, it is difficult to suggest that the employer is trying to "get rid of the union." On the other hand, a complete severing of relations, while not conclusive, lends more credence to the argument that an employer wishes to escape the obligations of collective bargaining. Therefore, while most of literature focuses on how many employees are "union," the more important question is how many employers are “union,“ as reflected in the number of local collective bargaining relationships. c. The importance of law and public policy. Another, though somewhat less distinctive, aspect of the American industrial relations system is that it occurs within a fairly well—defined legal framework (Bok and Dunlop, 1970; Cox, Bok, and Gorman, 1987). The outcomes of the bargaining process still depend upon the relative strength of the parties, but who must bargain with whom and over what are now largely matters of law. Since 1935, the most important law covering the private sector has been the National Labor Relations Act (29 USC 169) (hereafter referred to as the NLRA -a‘LiR‘VA 8 or the Act), which, under Section 7, grants workers the right to organize, bargain collectively, and engage in concerted activities—-the so-called "three basic rights." The Act also defines rules of conduct for unions and employers designed to protect the basic rights, and gives authority to an administrative agency, the National Labor Relations Board (hereafter referred to as the NLRB or the Board), to enforce the Act. Through its guidelines for union organizing and representation, the law codifies the importance of local relationships. Under Section 9 of the Act, employees must select or reject union representation at the "bargaining unit“ level—-a bargaining unit being a group of positions, usually at a single establishment, that share an apparent 'community of interest," and are, therefore, an appropriate unit for the purposes of collective bargaining (Weber, 1961). Production and maintenance positions within manufacturing often constitute an appropriate unit, as do clerical positions. If a majority of workers occupying the bargaining unit positions vote in favor of representation, the union is certified by the NLRB as its "exclusive bargaining representative" and the employer must confer with the union, and no other organization, group, or individual before altering “wages, hours, or other terms and conditions of employment," what are referred to as the "mandatory subjects 7““. 9 of bargaining.“ Equally important, once a relationship begins, it continues until some explicit action is taken to end it; there need be no periodic reaffirmation of a union’s right of representation. With these two aspects of the system in mind——the importance of local relationships and the related importance of the law to the industrial relations system-—it seems appropriate to bring the two together within the context of current questions of union decline: To what extent does the law, and indeed public policy more broadly, affect the viability of existing local relationships? D. A framework for studying the disappearance of local relationships. Much of the research concerning the effects of public policy on union dynamics examines the establishment of union representation. Authors have been particularly interested in the impact of the law and its enforcement on the success or failure of unions in. winning certification elections and securing first contracts (see, Roomkin and Block, 1981; Cooke, 1985; Dickens, 1983; Getman, Goldberg, and Herman, 1976; Weiler, 1983, 1990). Through this literature, which benefits greatly from the availability and precision of union election data, we have learned a good deal about the impact of employer speech, anti—union discrimination, and administrative delays on election outcomes. However, with 10 the exception of decertification elections, the representation process better explains the lack of union growth than the acceleration of union decline. It is important, therefore, to look beyond elections and focus on additional ways in which. public policy might affect the viability of local relationships. A common—sense model of union dynamics, as suggested by Chiason and Rose (1991), Dickens and Leonard (1985), Chiason and Dhavale (1990), Lawler (1990), and others, can easily be refined by dropping the variables relating to union growth and the contraction of employment to show that the total number of disappearances of local collective bargaining relationships are a function of the number of unionized business closings, unionized business relocations, complete substitutions of non—union labor for union labor, complete substitutions of technology for union labor, and union loss of certification. In equation form: EIXS=K2UBC+XUPR+ZNUL+ZTUL+ZLOS) [H Where: DIS: The disappearance of a local collective bargaining relationship. UBC: The closing of a unionized business. UPR: The relocation of a unionized business to a non- union site. ' NUL: The complete substitution of non—union labor for union labor. TUL= The complete substitution of technology for union labor. LOS: A union’s loss of certification as collective bargaining representative. 11 Upon a closer examination, we see that the model contains two broad categories of actions. The first four independent variables represent business decisions by employers that can affect the bargaining unit, resulting in either the immediate of ultimate loss of unit jobs and, perhaps, the bargaining unit relationship itself. The final variable is different; it concerns the right of a union to represent employees, a right that can be challenged either by employers or bargaining unit employees with no concurrent impact on jobs. If we assume the following... 1. Union leaders wish to preserve the collective bargaining relationship with the employer and their right to represent workers in a bargaining unit. That is, they are motivated by self—preservation. 2. Employers, in most cases, prefer the right to make business decisions unilaterally, without being compelled to bargain with a union. That is, they are motivated by a desire for control and certainty. 3. The degree to which unionized employers will act to escape collective bargaining relationships-—and, therefore, gain greater control and certainty—-is related to the amount of effort, associated costs, and relative benefits of doing so. 4. A legal requirement that employers bargain over business decisions that could result in a end to a bargaining relationship increases the associated costs and effort, and provides union leaders with an additional opportunity to pursue self— preservation. ;5.,_ A loss of certification is rare likely to occur when unions have less recourse against dissident \ «Kg-s 12 members, and when employers are allowed to intervene in the decertification process. ...the most relevant policy questions arising from Equation 1 are: 1. To what extent must an employer involve his or her union counterpart in a business decision that may, immediately or ultimately, result in the disappearance of the bargaining relationship? 2. To what extent can the union demand the allegiance of its members? 3. To what extent can the employer intervene in the decertification election process? 8. Research objective. When Congress passed the National Labor Relations Act in 1935, it enunciated a position that collective bargaining was a desirable institution and, as a matter of public policy, should be encouraged. Beyond the material benefits to workers, the framers of the Act also believed that it would eliminate a major source of industrial conflict by giving workers a statutory right to share in certain decisions affecting their employment. Voluntary collective bargaining would be good not just for labor, but for the economy and, hence, the nation (29 USC 169, Section 1). This belief still shows up in court decisions as the "neutral purposes of the Act' or some equivalent expression of the social usefulness of collective bargaining (see, for example, Fibreboard Prggugtg Corporation v. NLRB, 379 US 203, (1964); First 13 National Maintenance Corp. v,. NLRB, 452 US 666 (1981)). However, history teaches us that few participants in the system have taken such a dispassionate view. An enormous body of law has developed around the conflicts between employers and unions as to what the Act truly requires. The belief by some (particularly academic) observers at mid- century that the Act would provide the foundation for a stable and mature industrial relations system based on acquiescence to the law and the mutual recognition of rights proved illusory (Dunlop, 1958; Slichter, 1947). A. more enduring observation was the one made by Jack Barbash (1948, p.1) nearly 50 years ago: "No political democracy has offered a more hostile environment to unionism than has the United States." Even the employer-sponsored Taft—Hartley Amendments of 1947 did not create the neutral arena or level playing field that some seemed to have envisioned. In fact, the 1947 amendments may have led to more conflict by confusing the purposes of the Act (Forbath, 1989; Gross, 1995; Klare, 1981; Stone, 1981; Tomlins, 1985, 1985a). As former long—time Board member and chair John Fanning (1984, pp. 61, 63) commented: Labor relations has always been a field that arouses strong emotions—- sometimes more emotion than reason...As someone who has participated in some 25,000 decisions of the Board, I can assure you that the one factor every case has in common with the other is the II) I L l4 presence of at least two people who see things completely different. It is the job of government to arbitrate these differences of opinion. Whether the government ever was, or even should. be, a neutral arbiter is subject to debate. Regardless, since public policy is the product of political processes, decisional outcomes are likely to reflect the political balance of power. Historical evidence suggests that outcomes are more likely to favor organized labor when Democrats control critical positions, while business interests are more warmly received. when Republicans hold power (Kaufmann, 1991; Nagel, 1969). Certainly, organized labor’s tendency to endorse Democratic candidates with much greater frequency than Republican candidates reflects this belief (Delaney, Masters, and Schwochau, 1990; Lepo, 1992); and the same could be said for the favor shown to Republicans by the U.S. Chamber of Commerce and National Association of Manufacturers. Although these characterizations are somewhat sweeping, the 19803 provide a rather vivid-~perhaps extreme——example of the effects of partisan politics on labor relations public policy. Regardless of whether one believes that the policy changes of that decade were necessary adjustments to a system driven too far to the left (Irving, 1984; Miller, 1984; O'Connell, 1986; Walther, 1985) or right—wing attempts to 15 destroy bargaining protections (Clark, 1988, 1989; Gould, 1993; Gross, 1994), one must acknowledge that the political shift of 1980 began an era of fairly sharp departures from past doctrines. Some observers have complained that the changes of the 19805 went far beyond what was normally to be expected when the presidency shifts parties (Brownstone, 1986; Gross, 1994). Others have gone so far as to question the stability and even the adjudicatory integrity of the NLRB (Clark, 1988, 1989; Kaufmann, 1991). The immediate research objective is to examine the connections between the political changes of the 19805, changes in labor relations public policy——focusing on the three areas listed earlier-—and the viability of local collective bargaining relationships. It will be argued that policy changes in these areas reflected the wishes of a conservative federal administration, which took extraordinary steps to ensure that its ideology be transferred to decisional outcomes. The main features of the this ideology were a strong emphasis on the rights of employers to dispose of property unilaterally and without constraint, and anti- collectivisnlwith regard to employee relations. Changes both within the requisite governmental bodies and the resulting decisional outcomes will be reviewed. To explore the final part of the question, I will return tawthe model put forth in Equation 1. First, a regression 16 analysis will be performed on a model predicting the disappearance of local bargaining relationships across selected industries. The model is based upon the one suggested in Equation 1, but several important control variables have been added to improve specification. The goal of the regression analysis is to see which variables are the best predictors of the variance in local bargaining relationship disappearance rates across a sample of manufacturing industries from 1977 until 1990 using a pooled cross—sectional technique. Then, time period dummy and cross-product variables will be added to the model to test the stability of predictors. The technique, which is essentially a covariance model (Blalock, 1979) has been used in a couple of different forms, differing in the way in which variables have been added to the model. Allison (1982, 1984) demonstrated its use in his work on event history analysis, and a nearly identical technique was recommended by Gujarathi (1970) as an improvement upon the Chow (1960) test for the comparison of regression equations. The main hypothesis is that variance across industries will be found to have been more closely linked to the economic distress of industries, particularly as measured by firm failure rates (Dun and Bradstreet, 1974—1990). early in the period, but less associated with economic distress toward the.endrof 19808. Depending on results, two alternative 17 explanations are possible: If the proxies for business relocations and the substitution of inputs, and the variable for union decertifications explained an increasing amount of the variance as the decade progressed (i.e. if there is a significant change in one or more of the slope coefficients), it provides evidence that employers——in the case of decertification, also employees——may have been reacting to the policy changes that encouraged those behaviors. If the progress of time explained an increasing amount of variance (i.e. if there is a significant change in the model’s intercept), but no change in slope coefficients is observed, it provides evidence that some change, consistent with a policy explanation, is possible, but cannot be linked explicitly 11) a particular change 111 behavior. The null hypothesis is that the original model will not change with the introduction of time periods or cross-products (i.e. there will be no significant changes in either the slope or the intercept coefficients). Of course, time period dummy variables pick up all effects coincident to a particular period and not controlled for in the model. That is why the qualitative findings are just as important as the quantitative results. It will be argued that the magnitude of the policy changes of the mid— 19803 provide the most likely explanation for any changes in the predictive power of the independent variables. 18 Results may assist in the debate between the public policy and economic theorists by providing a policy focus in the area that has provided the economic theorists with their strongest arguments. Favorable results would support an argument that policy has affected the viability of previously established collective relationships, not just the probability of establishing new relationships. I. Chapters. In the next chapter, the main currents in the literature on union decline are identified, with. particularly close attention paid to economic and public policy explanations. In Chapter 3, the changes within public institutions are examined. The purpose of Chapter 3 is to show the unusual lengths that the federal administration went to in diffusing its conservative ideology. In Chapter 4 the products of this transformation, the reversals in public policy, are examined in light of the model of local union disappearance put forth above. In. particular, changes in an employer’s duty to bargain over business decisions, changes in a union's ability to maintain internal discipline, and changes in an employerfs ability to intervene in the decertification process are examined. The purpose of Chapter 4 is to demonstrate how decisional outcomes reflected more conservative notions of property relations and individual rights of association, and deemphasized bilateral solutions and collective rights. In 1.1:}. . 19 Chapter 5, I return to the independent variables mentioned in Equation 1 and examine the phenomena of plant closings, relocations, input substitution and decertifications. I detail changes and speculate on possible causes the for trends. Research hypotheses are then generated. In Chapter 6 the data and methods for the quantitative portion of the study are described. Findings are relayed in Chapter 7, and conclusions and final observations are found in Chapter 8. Chapter II. Literature Review. A. Introduction. The purpose of this chapter is to highlight main currents in the theoretical and empirical literature on the dynamics of union growth and decline. After a very brief overview of the varieties of this scholarship, I examine more closely two schools of thought. I first consider the more “purely economic" research, of which Ashenfelter and Pencavel’s 1969 article is seminal. Scholars working in this tradition tend to deemphasize historical phenomena and stress, instead, both cyclical and secular economic effects. Next, I examine the work of political economists and public policy analysts. In this research, unique historical trends embedded in the political histories of nation—states are central. Finally, I consider some of the problems in trying to bring these two schools of thought together. 8. Onion growth and decline. Over the years, scholars have proffered a number of theories for the growth and decline of the labor movement and the institution of collective bargaining. Some have focussed on individual and social attitudes toward unions (Farber, 20 '1' ..n .- at 21 1987; Hammer and Smith, 1978; Kochan, 1979; Lipset, 1986; Moody, 1988; Premack and Hunter, 1988); others have examined the performance of unions in attracting and maintaining members (Craft and Extejt, 1983; Dickens and Leonard, 1985). Still others have contributed to a large body of literature concerning the economic——usua11y macroeconomic——determinants of unionization, e.g. the business cycle, structure of employment, and foreign competition (Adams and Krislov, 1974; Ashenfelter and Pencavel, 1969; Bain and Elsheikh, 1976; Doyle, 1985; Dunlop, 1948; Hirsch and Berger, 1984; Hirsch and Addison, 1986; Jones, 1992; Manke, 1971; Neumann and Rissman, 1984; Troy, 1969, 1990). And lately, amidst calls for labor law reform, there is a growing literature on how public policy-—mainly the regulation of employer and union behavior— -affects the size and strength of the labor movement (Block, 1994; Chiason and Rose, 1990; Freeman, 1989, 1989a, 1989b; Goldfield, 1984; Gould, 1986, 1993; Gross, 1994; Weiler, 1983, 1990). Often, emphasis more than exclusion provides the basis for categorizing studies. But for present purposes, I will set aside the literature on individual and social attitudes, since it addresses a level and unit of analysis not found here. Rather, in dealing with industry trends over a period of time, the economic and public policy explanations seenlmost appropriate. These two fields borrow liberally from each LII s . .‘f '— - " 22 other, but there is a fairly large intellectual divide between those who advance historical explanations for union growth and decline and those who suggest more time invariant explanations (Stepina and Fiorito, 1986). The "purer economic" perspective links growth and decline with causes that could occur anywhere at any time, so long as certain economic antecedents, such as a rise in prices or employment, are present. The historical perspective, which dominates the political economy and public policy literature, focuses more directly on peculiar patterns of events leading up to or surrounding periods of growth and decline--war, legislative changes, changes in the national political mood, periods of worker unrest, etc. 1. Economic explanations. The idea that macroeconomic factors are the basic predictors of unionization trends dates back to at least World War I when George Barnett (1916), an early researcher of union growth, noted that changes in the size of the labor movement at the turn of the century followed closely the relative prosperity of the time. This general line of reasoning has been revisited many times since in analyses of the effects of prices, wages, and the structure of employment on unionization (Ashenfelter and Pencavel, 1969; Bain and Elshiekh, 1976; Dunlap, 1948; Hirsch and Addison, 1986; Jones, 1992; Manke, 1971; Sheflin, Troy and Koeller, 1981, Troy, 1990). Much of today’s research is in response to a seminal an“ I.’ .Iii 23 article written in 1969 by Ashenfelter and Pencavel. The dependent variable used in the study was the annual rate of change in the percentage of workers belonging to American unions. The authors examined the effects of price changes, employment and unemployment trends, union saturation, and political climate on the growth and decline of the labor movement between 1904 and 1960. Their strongest finding concerned prices, with a one percent change in consumer prices associated with a .65 percent change in the unionization rate. Ashenfelter and Pencavel concluded, therefore, that unions are largely defensive organizations which protect workers against a declining standard of living. When they entered into their equation several categorical variables representing particular time periods, they found no major changes in the coefficients. They write (p. 434): Although it is difficult to find one cohesive strand in the evidence, the most widely accepted view ascribes the bulk of trade union growth to what Bernstein has called periods of "social unrest.“ This paper seeks to show that there is no need to resort to such an ad hoc device to explain American union growth; a single behavioral relationship can explain the progress of the American labor movement in the twentieth century. There have been a number of responses to the Ashenfelter and Pencavel model. Generally, scholars have experimented with the model by updating the time series, improving measurement, and altering the specification (Adams and v i a 24 Krislov, 1974; Bain and Elsheikh, 1976; Jones, 1992; Mancke, 1971; Moore and Pearce, 1976; Neumann and Rissman, 1984; Sheflin, Troy, and Koeller, 1981). Mancke (1971) was one of the first to respond to Ashenfelter and Pencavel. Using as his dependent variable the level of unionization among workers in ”unionizable employment" he respecified Ashenfelter and Pencavel’s model by including a dummy variable to separate the periods of 1904 to 1937 and 1938 to 1960. He found that a significant shift had occurred following 1937, and concluded that "the Wagner Act caused a major structural change in American labor markets (p. 193)." Not long after Mancke, Bain and Elshiek (1975) provided one of the most comprehensive treatments of this question. First developed on data in Great Britain, the authors extended their analysis to the United States. They made several fairly minor adjustments to the Ashenfelter and Pencavel model to improve specification, and included a measure of wage change to reflect the "credit“ of unionization (and to balance Ashenfelter and Pencavel’s ”threat” effect of prices). They found that the basic formula suggested by Ashenfelter and Pencavel continued to perform well. In a response to Moore and Pearce (1976), who argued that the Ashenfelter and Pencavel model was sufficient for explaining trends prior to, but not after, War World II, 25 Elsheikh and Bain (1978) showed that their alternative model held constant for the entire period. In 1981, Sheflin, Troy, and Koeller retested both the Ashenfelter and Pencavel and Bain and Elshiekh models. The authors not only extended the time series to 1975, but corrected the sketchy early twentieth century membership data1 and used a maximum likelihood estimate of parameters rather than the more typical ordinary least squares technique. They found that, indeed, a shift had occurred, not in 1945 as Moore and Pearce had found, but in 1937 as the earlier work of Mancke had indicated. After about fifteen years of reshaping and rerunning the Ashenfelter and Pencavel model, it seemed fairly clear that prices and employment were good predictors of union trends, and that passage of the Wagner Act had had a significant effect on union growth as well. The stability of this model was once again questioned, however, after the sharp and rapid decline in unionization in the early 19805. Scholars returned to the question of whether a “single behavioral relationship" could explain growth and decline over the long— term. Leo Troy (1990), one of the co—authors of the 1981 study, argued that the basic econometric model needed to include some measure representing the structural shift in the ‘ Most of the early estimates were based on union self- reports, some of which included Canadian membership. 26 economy away fron1 heavy manufacturing (e.g. basic steel) toward light manufacturing (e.g. computer components) and, particularly, services. He also took note of the increases in part—time, female, and public sector employment. To test this added speculation, Jones (1992) created a modified version of the Ashenfelter and Pencavel model. Instead of using Ashenfelter and Pencavel’s measure of total union saturation, she employed a measure of union penetration within the four historically most unionized industries. Indeed, Jones concluded that Sheflin, Troy, and Koeller and later Troy were both correct. A change had occurred in the explanatory power of the Ashenfelter and Pencavel model after 1937. and structural shifts in the economy away from the traditionally more unionized sectors did provide most of the explanation for the decline in recent years. She writes (p. 266): Thus it would appear that the union membership declines of the 19705 and 19805 do not require period—specific explanations but, instead, represent a continuation of factors affecting union membership growth that were evident before the current decline began to appear. ‘The one minor concession to historicism allowed by scholars following in the mode of Ashenfelter and Pencavel is the single transition point of 1937, which. was, without question, a pivotal period in American industrial relations. _ u“. L 27 Otherwise, they argue that the dynamics of unionism are tied to economic trends——not political shifts, nor changes in public policy, nor decreasing militancy by unions, nor increasing militancy by employers. A number of authors have challenged this view. Farber (1987) in an article appearing in the journal Science noted that, first, structural economic changes do not provide a causal explanation, but at best can "account for" the loss in union members. Moreover, he explored how much of the recent decline could, in fact, be accounted for by structural shifts in the economy, and found that of the 5.4 percentage point decline in unionization between 1977 and 1984, shifts in employment between industrial sectors accounted for only 1.1 percentage points, or roughly 20 percent of the drop. Furthering Farber's point, Weiler (1989, cited in Chiason and Rose, 1991) criticized the structural theorists for their silent assumption that, for some reason, female and part—time workers in emerging industries are unorganizable. Like Farber, he argued that their models do not explain why workers in emerging industries are not organizing. After all, Weiler noted, the single most highly organized occupation in the country is a female-dominated, white collar profession--teaching. 28 2. Policy issues. Those who reserve the most criticism for the structural, economic explanations are political economists and public policy experts who note differences, both across nations and within nations over time, that do not seem to be linked to particular economic trends. As substitutes for the economic and structural explanations, these scholars prefer to focus on differences and changes regarding the posture of employers toward unions, the ability of unions to respond, and, particularly, the role of the state in regulating labor— management relations. Historical trends and political changes are central to this line of research. a. International and comparative research. Observers of international and comparative industrial relations provide some of the most compelling reasons for policy analysis. They note that while some of the economic studies have shown empirically impressive results, they have not always held up well to cross—national comparisons. A number of scholars (Visser, 1988; Freeman and Medoff, 1984; Freeman, 1989, 1989a, 1989b) have observed that purely economic variables cannot account for the disparity in unionization trends across nations experiencing similar economic conditions, and suggest that other international differences, particularly' government policies, need. to be taken into account (Chiason and Rose, 1990; Freeman, 1989, 29 1989a, 1989b; Freeman and Medoff, 1984; Freeman and Pelletier, 1990; Murphy, 1988; Weiler, 1983). Britain and Ireland and the United States and Canada provide vivid examples. While the two pairs of nations faced similar economic pressures during the 19805, their political histories diverged significantly. Britain and the U.S. were led by governments with strong conservative and anti— collectivist views: Thatcher’s battle with the National Union of Miners was similar to Reagan’s action against PATCO; what Thatcher accomplished through the Trade Union Laws, Reagan managed through appointments to the federal courts and the National Labor Relations Board. Meanwhile the trade union movements of Ireland and Canada flourished (Chiason and Rose, 1990; Freeman, 1989, 1989a, 1989b; Freeman and Medoff, 1984; Freeman and Pelletier, 1990). Canada, in particular, has been used as a frequent basis for comparison with the United States (Block, 1994; Chiason and Rose, 1990; Freeman and Medoff, 1984; Gould, 1993; Murphy, 1988; Weiler, 1983). Freeman and Medoff (1984, p. 227), in dismissing the structural change arguments, write: The major structural changes in the U.S. labor market-—growth of white—collar jobs, decline of manufacturing, increased number of women in the labor force——have occurred in virtually all major western economies. If structural changes were the chief factor behind the decline in unionism, the proportion organized would fall everywhere....Perhaps most telling 30 is the fact that the country most like the United States, Canada, where many of the same unions and firms operate, the percentage unionized went from below the U.S. percentage unionized to above it. They continue, borrowing from Weiler (1983), (p. 242): The principal difference between unionization in the United States and in Canada is that U.S. laws allow management to conduct lengthy, well—funded election campaigns against unions. Canadian labor laws do not permit such activity...The result is growing private sector unionization in Canada. The same theme is repeated by Chiason and Rose (1990) and again by Freeman (1989). Block (1994) also notes differences between the U.S and Canada, but rather than focusing on doctrinal differences in the law suggests that Canadian public agencies have done a better job of maintaining the system of collective bargaining. In Canada, labor law enforcement mechanisms work better and function more neutrally, and the provincial legislatures have been more attentive to the changing needs of the law than has the U.S. Congress. b. Domestic research. In addition to the comparative literature, there is a good deal of research on cross-sectional differences among states and regions within the U.S.—-usually differences regarding the presence or absence of state right—to—work laws or public employee bargaining statutes (Hirsch, 1980; Moore 31 and Newman 1975, 1985, 1988)--and on trends in policy and policy effectiveness over time. A :major focus of the longitudinal research is the increase in employer opposition to unionization, and the inability or unwillingness of the government to respond. The issue of employer oppositrmi has been around for some time, and gave rise to attempts to amend the NLRA in the late—19705 (Prosten, 1979). However, several studies in the early-19805 provided better and even more compelling accounts of the severity of the problem. In a detailed analysis of NLRB election results, Roomkin and Block (1981) found what had long been suspected: the longer a representation campaign lasted, the greater the probability that employees would choose against union representation. vmnler (1983) seized on this point, and in a truly influential article in Harvard Law Review examined employer behavior during organizing drives. Most alarming to Weiler was the increase in unfair labor practice charges filed against employers over the years, compared to the decrease in the number of union elections. Making some rough calculations--which have been criticized In! others (Goldberg, Brett anxi Getman, 1984; Irving, 1987; LaLonde and Meltzer, 1991)——Weiler concluded that one—in—twenty employees involved in union organizing campaigns have faced illegal discharge. Whether precise or not, the figure was picked up by others and became a key 32 issue during Congressional hearings held in 1984 (U.S. House of Representatives, 1984a). Cooke (1985), in turn, found that employer opposition did not end with the election campaign. In about 25 percent of the cases he surveyed, employers and unions were unable to arrive at a first contract settlement. These relationships had "died on the vine." Cooke also found that a significant predictor of the failure to settle was the extent of employer unfair labor practice activity. He concludes (p. 178): The evidence presented in this study clearly indicates that the rights of many workers to bargain collectively with employers are being denied. Ironically, the very agency responsible for the protection (Hf these rights, time NLRB, appears to be in part an unwitting accomplice tx> employers hoping t1) deny these rights to workers. Not everyone believed that the complicity of the Board was "unwitting. " Indeed, there was a growing chorus of critics who complained that the Board, acting on behalf of the Reagan administration, was quite deliberate in eroding the Act’s protections. Bluestone and Bluestone (1992, p. 76) write: In the new administration of Ronald Reagan, corporate lobbyists found.ea willing partner to help them rebuild profits by slashing federal taxes and government regulations... Summarily discharging all of the striking air traffic controllers in 1981 and placing new pro—management members on the National Labor Relations Board effectively deregulated the 33 rules under‘ which. organized labor management had been bound. Heckscher (1988, p. 35) adds: The disastrous effects of the NLRB’s anti—union tilt during the Reagan Administration are tine most recent indications that the fortunes of the labor movement are closely bound with the favor of the state. and Present NLRB chair William Gould (1993, p. 78) writes of the erosion of labor’s rights under the stewardship of "the free market buccaneers of the Reagan administration." the NLRB, he states (p. 22): It is certainly true that the Board, particularly ‘under time chairmanship <3f Donald Dotson between 1983 and 1986, was preoccupied with a mission to reverse a series of decisions that might promote the collective bargaining process. The appointments made to the Board were one— sided and pro—management. And of And from James Gross (1994, p. 48), a leading authority on the Board and author history: Republican Boards, particularly the Dotson Board, elevated. managements’ authority to manage above employers’ statutory obligation to bargain. During the Reagan presidency in particular, the Dotson board seriously diminished the statutory obligation to bargain, once considered central tx> the Act, by excluding management decisions too important to en1 employers’ business to have to be negotiated with a union. Many of these decisions have the most direct impact on jobs. of a :multi~volume work on its 34 Exactly what the "disastrous effects (Hecksher, 1989)" were is not certain. There is a lot of evidence that court decisions and Board processes and outcomes became increasingly favorable to employers during the 19805. For example, it has been shown that dismissals of unfair labor practice charges against employers increased. 300 percent between 1983 and 1985 (Bernstien and Gold, 1985), and that having a charge of anti—union discrimination upheld against an employer decreased by 35 percent for the period between 1983 and 1988 (Leap, Hendrix, Cantrell, and Taylor, 1990). Less certain is what the impact of this new environment was for industrial relations more generally and particularly for the viability of local relationships. C. Bridging the literature. Even if the political events of past couple of decades are put aside, the period was an extremely turbulent one. The post—War expansion stalled in the early 19705, as the domestic economy became increasingly challenged by production abroad. The oil embargo of 1973 was one of the first signs of this vulnerability. But, in fact, during the past couple of decades foreign trade has increased from approximately 9 to over 21 percent of gross domestic product (Dunlop Commission Report, 1995). This change itself is believed to have had a drastic impact on the industrial relations system. When the U.S. was a net exporter of goods, unions could 35 organize entire industries and "take wages out of competition," while employers could easily pass higher prices on to consumers who were limited in their product choices. As products made by foreign workers, who are beyond the reach of American laws and American unions and in many cases earn much less, began entering the market more frequently, domestic employers sought lower wages, productivity improvements, or both. To the extent that unions provided an obstacle t1) these changes, employers sought txn avoid them (Block, 1990; Block and McClellan, 1985; Farber, 1987; Kochan, Katz, and McKersie, 1986). Nonetheless, Stepina and Fiorito (1986, p. 248) write: [A] limited number of variables can account for' much. of the ‘variation of union growth, but to more fully explain and appreciate the dynamics of union growth, variables must be included which capture unique historical events. Some movement (already Imus occurred 1J1 this direction; Ihowever, tflma examination (of variables, and of historical variables in particular, has been very limited. It is easy to agree with Stepina and Fiorito, but not easy to find a solution. Goldfield (1987) raises the problem when he points out that while a leading cause of recent union decline is "changes in public policy that tend to favor more and more the employers (p. 231)..." The special responsibility of the Reagan administration is not very convincing. It is certainly true that the policies are more overtly anti-union than any 36 administration since Herbert Hoover. Their effect, however, are completely entangled with the sharp economic recession and the resulting high unemployment that vmnflri certainly' have found unions on the defensive even if Jimmy‘ Carter“ or a Inore liberal ’pro— labor’ Democrat were in office (p. 53). Goldfield raises a difficult issue, how to disentangle the effects of political and economic factors. Ii have already suggested some possibilities in Chapter I: combine qualitative and quantitative methods and borrow from the strong points of both political and economic research. Further, exploring changes both across industries and over time may offer a solution, assuming that the economic trends across industries vary sufficiently. In the next chapter I begin the qualitative portion of the study by examining changes in the institutions of labor relations public policy. Chapter III. Institutional changes. A. Introduction. In this chapter I describe the changes within the public bodies responsible for labor relations policy. The primary, though not exclusive, focus is on the National Labor Relations Board. The historical record reveals that labor relations institutions that luui become somewhat stable I»! the early 19705, started to come under enormous pressure in the mid- 19705. By the early 19805, the mutual understanding between labor, business, and the federal administration of the protocols of policy were scrapped, and a strong ideological agenda was pushed by the administration, its allies in Congress, and business groups. The changes described below occurred mainly during the;period of 1980tfluxnxfl11983, though they were foreshadowed by earlier conflicts. B. A foreshadowing of conflict. During the 19705 and 19805, labor relations public policy experienced several challenges and underwent a number of changes (Kochan, Katz and McKersieq 1986). Following the 1973 oil embargo and concomitant economic contraction, the 37 38 stability which (to some extent) had developed between government, labor, and management during the years of post- war expansion began to erode. Although, as stated earlier, the National Labor Relations Act never became the vehicle of accommodation that some had expected, much of the bickering over the purposes of the law and the proper role of the National Labor Relations Board had subsided. The period between the passage of the Landrum—Griffin Act in 1959, which included a few amendments to the NLRA (29 USC 401), and the health care amendments of 1974 (88 Stat. 395) was relatively uneventful (McCulloch and Bornstien, 1972; Moe, 1985, 1987).1 However, at about mid—decade in the 19705 several episodes began fraying relations between organized labor and management groups at the highest levels and creating a climate in which conflict easily grew. Among the more noteworthy conflicts of the 19705 were the unsuccessful battle 13/ building trades unions tx> pass a "common-situs picketing" bill and the failed attempt of the labor movement to amend the National Labor Relations Act more generally (Moe, 1985, 1987; Moody, 1988). The former measure would have allowed construction unions to picket entire work 1 Gross (1995) notes that in the mid-19605 employers were beginning to unify their opposition to the NLRB. The most notable manifestation of this activity was the Labor Law Reform Group, which was given a forum for its concerns during hearings held by Senator Sam Earvin. None of the Group’s ideas became law. 39 sites during a labor dispute, in effect stopping all work, even among contractors or subcontractors not party to the primary dispute. The legislation was engineered by Secretary of Labor John Dunlop as a quid pro quo for union agreement on a more orderly (and less inflationary) system of construction bargaining. The measure was initially supported by President Ford, who withdrew his support amidst pressure from the Republican right-wing. Ford’s veto foi to Dunlop’s resignation from the Labor Department (Mills, 1980; Kochan and Osterman, 1994). The latter' measure ‘was more sweeping and involved several amendments tr>tflu2 NLRA designed primariLy to make union organizing easier by, among other things, increasing penalties for employer unfair labor practices during union organizing campaigns. The battle over the Labor Law Reform Act was a particularly frustrating one for organized labor. The measure had enough votes for passage in both houses of Congress, and.was supported.by President Carter, but died when a motion to stop a Republican filibuster failed by one vote (Prosten, 1979). What was particularly troubling to:many labor leaders was the active opposition of a number of employers who were simultaneously engaged in a top-level committee known simply as the "Labor Management Group." The Labor Management Group, which. included, among' others, AFL—CIC) Secretary-Treasurer 4O (later President) Lane Kirkland and the chief executive officers of DuPont and General Electric, was formed in 1976 to discuss concerns of mutual interest (e.g. inflation) and tc>chart a course for constructive labor—management relations. The Group gained semi—official status during Jimmy Carter’s presidency. Labor' leaders immi hoped tfimu: their‘ employer counterparts in the Group would remain neutral on the labor law reform bill. They did not (Moody, 1988). Speaking before a group in Harriman, N.Y., a clearly agitated Lane Kirkland (1978) stated: And there is a filibuster-— organized, promoted, and sustained, not just by some primitive sections of industry, but all of corporate America, through its major organs of influence. The circle is unbroken. No voice of compassion for (fine plight of ea worker stripped of his livelihood for having the character to overcome fear and exercise his legal rights has been heard in public from any official of a major corporation. There is a term for the kind of campaign that American industry has launched to kill the hopes of the most oppressed and deserving workers in this country. It is class warfare. Like the South African "Bruderbund," the unbroken phalanx, the conspiracy of silence of the supposedly enlightened and the hate— ridden invective of your Helmses and Hatches who do the corporate dirty work make it plain. By the late—19708, relations between labor and business groups were at a low point. Some were worried that the rift would lead to even more serious consequences. Senator Jacob 41 Javits, for example, warned that, "the relative peace between labor and business that the U.S. has experienced for several decades is now sorely strained and could break into open conflict (Daily Labor Report, August 28, 1978, p. A—7)."2 Perhaps it was almost inevitable that the problems would spread t1) time National Labor Relations Board” which. had become a remarkably stable agency after a tremendously turbulent beginning (Gross, 1981). That the Board should get dragged into such disputes is not surprising since it is at the heart of labor relations public policy, and has been caught in the crossfire between labor and management, liberals and conservatives more than once. Almost immediately eafter if}; establishment tn! the Wagner Act of 1935, the Board was attacked for its pro—union and, moreover, pro-CIO leanings. Added allegations of communist-influence and infiltration turned the Board into a political liability for President Roosevelt and. provided ammunition for many anti—New Deal members of Congress (Gross, 2 Since 1960, the Bureau of National Affairs, a private publishing company, has published the Dailnyabor Report. The Egg is an invaluable historical resource. It provides not only news items, but full texts of Board memoranda, Board_and court decisions, and speeches of Board members, labor and management advocates, and others. In fact, several information requests that I made to the Board were answered with references to the _D_L_R. Since news items in the DD}; appear without by—lines, they are cited as Daily Labor Report with the date and page number of the article. Speeches, memoranda, etc., are cited by author's name. 42 1974; Millis and Brown, 1950; Scher, 1956). The Board also became a favorite target for the press, with the steady drumbeat of bad publicity leading to a rather low opinion of the Board and the Act on the part of the public. Several major newspapers-—some of which were facing organizing drives-—attempted to lay blame for the late—30s economic slowdown (the so—called "recession within the depression") on the Act. In the 1938 election, Republicans gained 81 seats in house, doubling their presence there, and picked up 8 Senate seats. Not a single incumbent Republican was defeated. Of course there were many issues in the campaign, but Gallup polls revealed that, indeed, Americans had. doubts about the .Act. Senator~ Wagner; the Board’s architect (and chair of its NIRA prototype), although victorious in his first post—Act election, received 350,000 fewer votes in 1938 than he had in 1932 (Gross, 1981 pp. 73- 74). By 1940, amendments to curtail the Board’s power were being' sought :hi Congress. And vwnfli Republicans finally gaining a majority in both houses in 1946, the stage was set for some measure to pass. In the following year, major revisions did come with the Taft—Hartley amendments, paSsed over President Truman’s veto (61 Stat. 136, 1947). Taft—Hartley sought to "balance" the Act by, among other things, providing for a set of union unfair labor practices 43 to mirror the Wagner Act’s employer unfair labor practices, and In! instituting ea system cu? union decertification that would allow employees a means of ousting an incumbent union. The Act also made institutional changes at the Board by outlawing "economic" (read socialist) research, and by making the General Counsel, who serves as the Board’s prosecutor of unfair labor practices, a separately appointed position. Prior to the amendments, the General Counsel served at time pleasure <3f tlmz Board. Therefore time investigation, prosecution, and ultimately the judgement of unfair labor practices were contained within a single structure of authority. While the Board had made an effort to minimize potential conflicts-of—interest, some problems remained and business interests and Congressional conservatives complained that the Board was unable to carry out all of its functions fairly and objectively (Gross, 1981; Millis and Brown, 1950: Scher, 1956; Stryker, 1989). The separation between the General Counsel and Board has proven, at times, to be itself a source of conflict. In fact the first independent General Counsel, Robert Denham, a pro— Taft—Hartley Republican appointed by Harry Truman, battled continually and publicly with chairman Paul Herzog over the former’s claim that the Board had remained, even after the 1947 amendments, softer on unions than on employers. Pro— labor Democrats tried to get the General Counsel’s provision 44 rescinded, but were unsuccessful. Ultimately, on September 15, 1950, President Truman was persuaded to force Denham’s resignation (Gross, 1995, pp 58—71). But although Denham was out, the General Counsel’s independent authority remained intact. However, following’ DenhanVs departure relations between the Board and General Counsel calmed, at least temporarily. (Gross, 1995; Kaufman, 1991; McCulloch and Bornstein, 1974). Amidst the relative calm, one truly pivotal conflict did occur during the Eisenhower years that seemed to set the tone for the Board selections for years to cxmma .As might be expected, the Eisenhower Board was relatively more favorable to business interests than the Truman or Roosevelt Boards had been. But organized labor, at its apex in numbers, was in a fairly good position to make sure that business groups did not have a completely free hand in reshaping labor policy. When a distasteful nominee, Albert Beeson, was put forward by the President, a serious challenge was mounted (McCulloch and Bornstein, 1974; Scher, 1956). Labor’s fight was carried forwand by Senator John F. Kennedy, who subjected Beeson to an extraordinarily rigorous confirmation hearing. Kennedy argued that Board appointees deserved particularly close scrutiny because of the quasi- judicial nature of their work. Unlike cabinet posts, where the president had.ea right t1) expect ideological loyalty, 45 Kennedy argued that Board appointees should be above partisan politics and as ideologically neutral as possible. Although Beeson was ultimately confirmed by a 45 to 42 vote, Kennedy’s arguments seemed to provide a philosophical basis for future Board nominations (McCulloch and Bornstien, 1974, p. 62). Eisenhower’s next appointment was John Fanning, a Democrat and career civil servant who would end up being reappointed by' both. Democrats and Republicans, ultimately serving a record 25 years on the Board. When Kennedy himself assumed the presidency, the Board again swung in a direction somewhat more favorable to labor, but trilateral relations between labor, management, and the Board were maturing and stabilizing. No major attempts were made to reshape the Board, and for the next decade or so both Republicans and Democrats were routinely appointed to second, third, and even fourth terms. One of Kennedy’s appointments, Howard Jenkins, 53 Republican, would serve fin: the next 20 years, retiring at about the same time as Fanning. Jenkins and Fanning took the same side on many issues, and together embodied the stability which had developed at the Board. A couple of Congressional hearings were held during the 19608- —first by Illinois Representative Roman Pucinski in 1961 and then by North Carolina Senator Sam Earvin in 1969--to air complaints about the Eisenhower and Kennedy/Johnson Boards respectively, but neither resulted in any significant 46 Congressional action (McCulloch and Bornstien, 1974). Even the change in White House politics in 1968 failed tr) make 61 dramatic difference. 131 1974, McCulloch. and Bornstien (p. 76) noted: The Nixon NLRB, contrary to labor’s worst fears and.management’s highest hopes, has not engaged in any systematic program to reverse prior Board precedents on any wholesale basis. Although changes in.tflu2 political affiliathmi of the president had always meant some change in the ideological make-up of the Board, a system of accommodation had clearly developed” Organized ljflxn: realized timn: its role 1J1 the selection process would be an active one during Democratic administrations, 1mm: more advisory 111 nature during Republican years. Business groups shared a similar understanding of the relative balance of power, and expected more active involvement when Republicans held. the ‘White House. Referring to the Board in the mid—19705, Moe (1985, p. 1096) writes: The political controversy and passionate disputes that surrounded the NLRB in its early years have subsided dramatically, and for the last two decades it has rarely been a salient focus of partisan politics. Indeed it has come to be regarded by both sides of the political fence as one of the most professional, efficient, and successful government agencies, processing vdxii fairness and dispatch untold thousands of cases every year. 47 Comments surrounding the appointment of Betty Southard Murphy as NLRB chair by President Ford give evidence of how the systemiworked. AFL~CIO Public Relations Director Al Zack told the press that while Murphy was "obviously not our nominee," the federation had no objection to her appointment. Zack went on to describe Murphy as fair and honest, and stated that the nomination was "well-deserved (Daily Labor Report, January EL 1975, FL A-8)." At 1mm? confirmation hearings, endorsements of a:1nnflxmr of unions were entered into the record. However, even Murphy was unable to escape the growing tensions of the late—1970s. When Jimmy Carter became president he abruptly replaced her, giving the Chair’s job to John Fanning. While Board members have five year terms independent of tine president’s” the chair serves an; the president's pleasure. It was no surprise, therefore, that Carter should replace Murphy, but Fanning’s appointment had been leaked to the newspapers even before Murphy had been told of the change in command. A terse letter to her successor (Murphy, 1977, p. D—1) began: Although I have heard nothing at all from you, or from the current Secretary of Labor, or from anyone in the White House, I understand from my newspaper sources that President Carter will name you today to replace me as Chairman of the NLRB. In interviews, Murphy blamed her shabby treatment on 48 Secretary of Labor Ray Marshall, who she accused of wanting to become the "labor czar" (Daily Labor Report, April 14, 1977). Her bitter feelings did not subside quickly. When rumors began to stir that she would be asked to resume the chair in the mid—1980s, Murphy responded, "There is no way in God’s world that I would go back to the NLRB." Adding that she would "rather starve" than return.tx> the Board (Daily Labor Report, June 14, 1984, p. A4). Carter’s appointment of Fanning to succeed Murphy was not welcomed by the business groups, but there is no evidence that any serious challenge to it was mounted. However, when John Irving resigned as General Counsel in 1979 and William Lubbers was nominated to replace him, a major battle broke out. Lubbers had been an attorney at the Board for many years, serving on John Fanning’s staff for two decades. His nomination was vigorously opposed by business groups and at least two former Republican Board appointees. The Chamber of Commerce’s presence at Lubbers’s confirmation hearings marked the first time ever that a representative of that organization had actually appeared before Congress to oppose a Board nominee (Daily Labor Report, December 14, 1979, pp. F-4—F-10). The objections to Lubbers’s nomination. were centered (n1 his lack cflf private sector“ experience, but, moreover, his close relationship with Fanning, who ihad, 49 imprudently, endorsed him publicly. Complaints were raised that the Board would function in a pre—Taft—Hartley fashion, with little separation between the Board and General Counsel. Former Board chair Edward Miller likened the situation to the "Judge’s brother running for District Attorney (Daily Labor Report, December 14, 1979, p. AA—2)." It was equally clear that business was at least as concerned with the potential decisional outcomes as with protecting tine integrity cu? Board processes. In separate statements both the National Association of Manufacturers and the U.S. Chamber of Commerce made reference to Lubbers as the person responsible for "writing the many pro—union decisions of John Fanning (Daily Labor Report, November 30, 1979, p. A- 11)." I find it difficult to believe that the business groups would have been as vociferous in their opposition if the public records of the tmm>rmai had been more to their liking. But, in fact, both Fanning and Lubbers were career civil servants, both were Democrats, both were liberal, and both typically held positions favorable to labor. The Lubbers matter dragged on for some time. He mas given a recess appointment when Congress adjourned in 1979, and was finally confirmed in 1980 when a Republican filibustem‘ was overcome. Ifima fight over‘ the :nomination Proved a mere foreshadowing of what was to come in the early— 19808. When Ronald Reagan was elected to the presidency the 50 system of mutual accommodation was scrapped completely, and a major ideological overhaul of the Board began (Moe, 1987; Clark, 1986; Kaufmann, 1991). C. Open conflict at the Board. As is by now well—known, Ronald Reagan is something of a paradox in industrial relations history. He is the only U.S. president (1) have held tjma presidency cu? a national union, the Screen Actors Guild, but enjoyed little support from labor leaders during his time in the White House. His dismissal of striking air traffic controllers-~one of the few unions that had actually endorsed him——early in his presidency is still alluded to by many as a defining moment for labor-management relations in the U.S. during the 19808 (Bluestone and Bluestone, 1992; Trumka, 1987). I believe it is significant that Reagan himself (Reagan, 1990) writes that the pivotal events of his life were his battles math cxmmmnist—dominated unions :U1 Hollywood, his time spent filming a movie in Emgland during the post-war Labour government, and his relationship with corporate leaders while serving as a spokesman for General Electric. Together, he relays, these experiences taught him the virtues of industrial capitalism and the dangers of a labor movement that is too powerful and defines its social mission too broadly (Reagan, 1990, p. 119). He had supported the Screen Actors Guild, he writes, simply because it helped fledgling 51 actors during the days of Hollywood's studio system (Reagan, 1990, pp. 89—90). Throughout his years in political life, Reagan nurtured these views of capital and labor, and by the time he ran for president in 1976, his association with the labor movement was well in the past (Johnson, 1991). He was, for example, the only presidential candidate in the 1976 election to affirm his support for Section 14(b) of the Act, which allows states to adopt so—called "right—to-work" laws prohibiting union security agreements. All the other candidates, including George Wallace, expressed opposition (Daily Labor Report, March 17, 1976). With his election to the presidency in 1980, Reagan was given the opportunity to enact his beliefs and have a direct influence on labor policy. Urged on by the business lobby, and buoyed by time new Republican majority II] the Senateau- and with conservative Orrin Hatch leading the Labor Committee——President Reagan disposed of the tradition which had granted labor (particularly the AFL—CDO) a say in the selection process (Moe, 1987). Instead, tflma White HOuse pushed the candidacy of John Van De water to replace John 3 The Republican majority in the Senate is critical to this story. Without it the Administration may not have been as successful in the appointment process as it was. AFL-CIO Building Trades leader Robert Georgine felt that the Senate provided a larger obstacle to labor than did the White House (Daily Labor Report, January 2, 1981). 52 Fanning as Board chair and Robert Hunter to take the seat of member John Truesdale. Hunter had been counsel to the minority members of the Senate Labor' Committee during the late 1970s. In. that capacity he worked for Orrin Hatch, and had been credited with helping Hatch engineer the filibuster that killed the Labor Law Reform Act. He was also co—author of a 1981 Heritage Foundation report entitled Mandate for Leadership- —Policy Management in a Conservative Administration. In his chapter on labor law, Hunter called for repeal of the Act’s provisions allowing for union security agreements, a ban on the compulsory use of union hiring halls in construction, and a number of pro—business changes in the Act’s administration. Although labor groups did not support the Hunter appointment, his confirmation hearings were, nonetheless, uneventful (Daily Labor Report, September 10, 1981). The same could not be said for the concurrent hearings on nomination of John Van De Water for chair. The labor movement, having been excluded from the selection process, did not view Van De Water as the moderately pro—business type they had come to expect of a Republican nominee for chair. Rather, during much of his career he had worked as a legal consultant to businesses facing union organizing drives, and had once been quoted in a trade publication as saying that he had been involved in "130 union drives with the unions losing 53 125 (Daily Labor Report October 16, 1981, pp. F-l—F-2)." Van De Water was granted a recess appointment, but when the .Senate Labor Committee returned to his nomination, labor was able tx> gain enough support t1) deadlock the \Kflxa. Senate Majority Leader Howard Baker lumi considered relieving the committee of its control over the nomination and holding a floor vote despite the deadlock, but Van De Water had, in the meantime, managed to anger the National Right—to—Work Committee with a conciliatory gesture toward unions (Daily Labor Report September 1, 1982, p. A-3). (He stated a philosophical agreement vnlji agency sflmx) clauses). With opposition from kxmfli sides, Baker allowed van Ike Water's nomination to die (Daily Labor Report, November 19, 1981, p. AA—l). In retrospect, union leaders may wish that they had let the Van De Water nomination go through. Undaunted by the battle over Van De Water, the White House sent up to the Hill the name of Donald Dotson to be the next chair. Dotson was described as, anmxx; other things, "staunchly antiunion, a crusader for the Reagan cause, and a protege of Jesse Helms (Moe, 1987, p. 270)." He had once written a letter to the American Bar Association Journal which read, in part (U.S. House of Representatives, 1983, p. 44): [C]ollective bargaining frequently means labor monopoly, time destruction <3f individual freedom, and the destruction of the marketplace 54 as the mechanism for determining the value of labor. Fortunately for Dotson, he had previously gained Senate approval for a deputy secretary’s position at the Department of Labor, which made it very difficult. for that body to oppose his appointment to the Board. It appeared, as well, that the Senate ‘was tiring' of the conflicts over Board appointments. Seeing no hope of winning this time, the AFL— CIO dropped its formal opposition to the Dotson nomination and he was approved by a voice vote of the Senate (Daily Labor Report, February 17, 1983 p. A—5). Confirmed at about the same time as Dotson was Los Angeles Attorney Patricia Diaz Dennis. Although a registered Democrat, Dennis was a Reagan supporter, in—house counsel to the American Broadcasting Company, and a self—professed conservative with regard to labor relations matters (Dennis, 1986). Dotson and Dennis joined Hunter, a soon—to-retire Howard Jenkins, and Donald Zimmerman on the Board. Zimmerman was a political independent and Carter appointee, who dissented on a number of critical decisions (see following chapter). Therefore, a solid conservative majority gained control of the Board on May 5, 1983, the day of Dennis’s swearing-in. Recall, however, that General Counsel Lubbers was appointed in 1980. Since the General Counsel also has a five 55 year term, Lubbers was to remain at his post another 18 months or so. This overlap was perhaps the most contentious in Board history since the Herzog—Denham days, and revealed the depth of the ideological rift between the Dotson Board and its predecessors (Gross, 1995; U.S. House of Representatives, 1983). The largest public dispute between Dotson and Lubbers involved the Chairman’s plan to move control over the Board’s Enforcement Section, which seeks federal court enforcement of Board orders, from the General Counsel's office to the Solicitor’s Office. It was Dotson’s view that attorneys in the section had not been providing the Board with adequate representation before the courts. Under his plan, attorneys would serve at the pleasure of the Board and would be supervised by the Board Solicitor and Deputy Solicitor, who are not independently appointed. All pleadings before the courts would, henceforth, contain the signature of the Solicitor, not the General Counsel. Dotson was careful to point out that the enforcement function had not been placed with the General Counsel by the Taft—Hartley amendments, but had been ceded to that office by the Board itself in 1955 (U.S. House of Representatives, 1983). The Chairman now wanted the authority back. The question union leaders, members of Congress, and labor journalists were asking was, Why now? Was there some 56 emergency to warrant changing a 30 year old practice? The ostensible issues CRHI be seen i11 the following exchange, which took place between Chairman Dotson and Member Zimmerman at a Board meeting on May 4, 1983. The meeting had been closed to the public, but the minutes surfaced following a Congressional 1983). 1301'. son : Zimmerman: Dotson: Zimmerman: DOCSOI’I: Zimmerman: Dotson: Zimmerman: DOt SOD: subpoena (National Labor Relations Board, What liemn concerned about here is the way this Agency is perceived by the public. I'd like for us not to have the reputation and image of being high—handed. I’d like us to be effective iji enforcing the Statute. I think we can do that and I think at the same time we will achieve more respect and credibility with the public. ZUmi I don’t see that attitude. I don't see that from the General Counsel. 21 have had complaints universally about that and a lot of that centers around the activities of these people [the enforcement lawyers]. Well, our experience has apparently been quite different. Well, how many cases have you tried in the Court of Appeals? I haven’t tried any, but I have been in touch in the 2 1/2 years I’ve been on the Board with attorneys who do across the country and on both sides and... Maybe we've been in touch with different attorneys... Possibly so, but the statements I have heard are quite complimentary of this Agency generally. I’ve heard and Mdtnessed some the sleaziest tactics I have ever seen, the kind of stuff I would not retain if they [sic] were working for me. Can you give me an example? I am not going to give you examples 57 because I don’t want to single people out. Upheaval followed. Congress intervened, and a series of very stormy hearings were held. Massachusetts Representative Barney Frank pressed Dotson to be mpre specific about what "sleazy tactics" he was talking about and by whom. When the Chairman was unable or unwilling to do so, Frank stated (U.S. House of Representative, 1983, p. 58): II want to lma straightforwand and tell you that I am persuaded in part by what I have read and what I have heard here today. But the decision to do this was motivated more by a sense that views of the General Counsel and those employed in the Enforcement Section were no longer representative of the Board majority and of the Solicitor. And. that the reason for this, I think, fairly substantial shift in authority had to do with a desire to change the philosophy being expressed. What Zimmerman, Frank and others were concerned about was that Immson’s comments about time public image CHE the Board, etc., were largely subterfuge. “flue Chairman’s real concern was that Lubbers would represent Board decisions to the courts in manner assuring an outcome more consistent with General Counsel’s pre—Reagan Board views of the Act than with the views expressed by the Board’s new majority. Dotson’s true agenda, the dissenters felt, was to consolidate conservative control of the Board (U.S. House of Representatives, 1983). 58 What was particularly troubling to those testifying at Congressional hearings was tflmfl: the person Vflu) would gain immediate authority under the new plan was sitting Board Solicitor, lhmfli Reilly. Reilly lmmi been 5m1 assistant to Dotson at the Labor Department, but more important, had acted as counsel for the plaintiff in Beck v. Communication Workers (108 S. Ct. 2641, 1988), the now—famous case which placed strict controls on the allowable use of union dues revenues. Moreover, Reilly’s time while working on the Beck case was paid for by the National Right to Work Legal Defense Foundation, the legal action wing of the National Right to Work Committee, the most prominent anti—union group in the nation. The Deputy Solicitor would be Eugene Slade, an attorney from Member Hunter’s staff (U.S. House of Representatives, 1983) . Since Dotson had received the votes he needed to push the plan ahead, not much could be done to stOp it, and the General Counsel’s role was diminished. When Lubbers’s term finally expired, the General Counsel’s job went to Rosemary Collyerq‘ formerly of the Mine Safety and Health Commission. Collyer was attacked. by ‘ For a short period, Wilford Johansen, former head of the NLRB's Los Angeles office, served as Acting General Counsel. Later, Johansen was given a seat on the Board along with. Marshall Babsony a management attorney and. Reagan— Democrat. The two were appointed in the summer of 1985 to the seats formerly occupied by Members Zimmerman and Jenkins. Jenkins’s seat had been vacant for over a year. 59 organized labor for having had relatively little labor law experience and for her reputation for siding with employers during her time on the Commission. The AFL-CIO formally and rather ‘vigorously' opposed lmnr nomination. (AFL—CIO, .1983). She was confirmed nonetheless, and by the summer of 1984 both branches of the NLRB were in conservative hands. D. Impact of the new Board. The effects of the Board’s transformation were quick and dramatic. Former member Peter D. Walther (1986), a supporter of the Dotson Board, noted 29 major reversals of doctrine in less than two years. Legal scholars, and even a few employers, became concerned. over the unpredictability of Board. decisions (Brownstone, 1986; Estreicher, 1986; Kaufmann, 1991). A number of Board practices came under immediate scrutiny. There were the obvious complaints about outcomes, for example the 300 percent increase (in Dotson’s first full year) in the number of dismissals of unfair labor practice charges filed against employers, while dismissals of union unfair labor practice charges held constant (Bernstein and Gold, 1985). But, additionally, critics were concerned about a number of other Board practices: its extraordinary disregard for precedent (Estreicher, 1986), the huge and growing of backlog of cases, and its practice of "icing" cases (Brownstone, 1986). 1"N J d is." a- “A 5“; 60 Policy oscillations at the Board are nothing new (and will be discussed in the next chapter). The Kennedy Board, for example, reversed a number of Eisenhower Board precedents, and the Nixon board overruled a few Kennedy/Johnson Board decisions (Gross, 1995). But by the mid-1980s legal experts, advocates, and several of the circuit courts, were growing increasingly restless with the tendency toward zero—based jurisprudence displayed by the Board. The Seventh Circuit angrily denied enforcement of a case simply because the Board had flip—flopped on the issue so many times (Mosey Manufacturing, 701 F2d 610, 1983). But even though the Board was never known for a slavish adherence to precedent, the vigor with which the Dotson Board pursued policy reversals seemed to some observers extraordinary. In a number of leading cases, the Board-—now through the Solicitor's Office-—asked for cases back before the courts even had a chance to decide on enforcement or remand. New York University Law Professor Samuel Estreicher (1986) commented: The National Labor Relations Board has made the labor law professor’s job a nightmare... These days the BNA labor service treats us to a reversal a week by the NLRB, sometimes coupled with notice that the Board has asked a court of appeals to remand a case to it for reconsideration. How is my tennis game going to improve under these circumstances? 61 The Board’s backlog of cases was also a major concern during 19803. Again, the issue was not a new one. During the Kennedy administration a bill referred to as Plan No. 5 was introduced in Congress. The legislation was designed to speed-up Board processes by granting more authority to lower— level officials to dispose of unfair labor practice cases. While the plan had a good deal of support, it was opposed by key employer groups, and ultimately failed. Again in the 19705, Chairwoman bhummmr had mmestled Mdth.em1 increasing backlog, particularly after the Board’s jurisdiction ‘was extended to cover hospitals by the 1974 health care amendments (House of Representatives, 1975, 1976). As bad as the problem had been, it got worse in the 19805. But more disturbing, the backlog was growing even after the number of cases coming into the Board began declining (U.S. House of Representatives, 1983a, 1984b). The House Government Operations Committee met continually during the 19805 to consider the problem of the backlog (U.S House of Representative 1983a, 1984b, 1985, 1986, 1987, 1988). Scores of aggrieved workers testified on how they had been left hanging while their unfair labor practice charges crawled through the system. Although a few employers also expressed concern——due to the effects of delay on the compounding of potential backpay liability——the issue was particularly a problem for unions and union activists. 62 A clear message is sent about the risks of mulitancy when workers must wait for several years to find out whether they will be returned to their jobs. By 1988, the final year of Dotson’s chairmanship, the median interval between filing a charge and judicial enforcement of an order was 1,192 days, or over three years (LaLonde and Meltzer, 1991, p. 964).5 To compare the backlog problem during the Dotson years with earlier administrations, consider that the average number of "old" cases still pending at the beginning of a fiscal year had been 595 for the five years prior to Dotson’s chairmanship, but 1107 during the five years of his chairmanship. This increase occurred despite a total decline in case intake from nearly 60,000 cases in 1980 to fewer than 40,000 by 1988 (U.S. House of Representatives, 1988; National Labor Relations Board, 1990). In short, intake dropped by one—third while the backlog doubled. Chairman Dotson claimed that the extraordinarily high turnover of Board seats in the early 1980s was the leading reason for the backlog (Dotson, 1984; U.S. House of Representatives, 1983a, 1984b). He did acknowledge, however, 5 These types of delays occur when the parties can not agree on the settlement of an unfair labor practice charge. Most cases are settled fairly quickly when either a Regional Director finds no merit to a charge or an employer (or union) agrees to settle a charge informally. If decisions are contested, however, the process can become extremely protracted. 63 that at least part of the problem was due to "iced" cases. Icing is the practice of holding back cases that contain issues the Board is considering for reversal until a case with a.rmnxe favorable fact pattern—-and, hence, easier to argue before the courts-—emerges. Because of the unusually large number of areas the Board wanted to change, at the end of Dotson's first year as chair, the Board had 600 cases on ice, or about half its total backlog. Once off the Board, member Zimmerman complained, "It would have been preferable in my judgement to have slated fewer cases [for icing] and to have decided the rest according to existing precedent rather than hold up as many as they did (Brownstone, 1986, p. 271)." By the mid-1980s, it was difficult to find a neutral voice when the Board was being discussed. The centerpiece of the controversy was a volume published by the U.S. House of Representatives in October of 1984 entitled The Failure of American Labor Law--A Betrayal of American Workers (U.S. House of Representatives, 1984a). The report followed a series of Committee hearings during which an overwhelming number of witnesses——mainly union leaders, lawyers, and academics—-pilloried the Board and its practices. Several labor leaders even called for a root-and—branch repeal of the Act as a means of getting rid of the NLRB (U.S. House of Representatives, 1983, pp. 6—27; Gould, 1993, p. 153). The Committee concluded that the law was failing due to u u- a. ..A‘ an- 64 increasing employer opposition, and the Board's "administrative crisis," "pmditicization," aumi "bias (UflS. House of Representatives, 1984a, p. 25)." Since 1985 marked the Board’s 50th anniversary, there were plenty of occasions at numerous conferences and in scores of special edition publications to continue the debate. Battle lines were clearly drawn. On one side stood those, like Professor Frank Murphy, who stated (Murphy, in Morris 1987, p. 77): The year 1985 marked the 50th year since the enactment of the National Labor Relations Act. What should have been a joyful golden anniversary instead has been a year characterized by a number of sad ironies. It is a sad irony that the statute which in its early years encouraged the growth of unionism has increasingly become a promise to the ear broken to the hope and is today viewed in many respects as a hollow mockery. It is a sad irony that the statute passed.to promote unionismland collective bargaining ii; today' consciously' turned against itself to the statutory objectives by the most blatantly anti- union Board in history. On the other side, stood those, like labor attorney Charles Bakaly, who in response to Murphy said (Bakaly, in Morris, 1987, p. 94): It is self-evident that the Board is not responsible for foreign imports or deregulation. Nor is ii; directly responsible for the recent ability of employers to operate during strikes...[C]ases are being processed in 65 much the same way as they have in the last 20 years. Admittedly unions are not winning 84 percent of the cases against employers as they were during the Carter years...[But] [t]o argue that this Board is not fulfilling its statutory obligations is simply without foundation. It is even more interesting to compare the comments of labor officials at the time of the Board’s 50th anniversary with those Ci :hmfi: ten years before. While attending a celebrathmi of the Emerd’s 40th anniversary-—also, by the way, during the time of a Republican administration-~AFL-CIO President George Meany (1975, D—l) remarked: [I]t is only fair to state the obvious- -the NLRB, laboring in cmmacof the most adversary—prone areas of government, has a commendable record. With few exceptions, none current, it has been led by men and women of honor, whose capability and expertise are well known. It has been staffed by men and women who are truly public servants, whose hard work and devotion to duty is often overlooked... I have had the opportunity to observe the workings of a host of state and federal agencies and my experiences is that the PHJUB has been consistently far better than most. In this imperfect world, your sustained high level of performance is ea substantial accomplishment. No such kudos were in store for the Board upon its golden anniversary; I found no evidence the AFL—CIO's participation in any anniversary festivities. Instead, federation representatives wrote (Bernstein and Gold, 1985, 213): 66 [I]f labor chooses to celebrate this landmark anniversary, it will do so with anger toward the Act’s principal custodian, the National Labor Relations Board. Why is the act’s golden anniversary so bittersweet? ..Ronald Reagan has packed the NLRB in management’s favor to an unprecedented degree, converting it ideologically into a weapon against the labor movement. And concerning the Chairman himself, AFL—CIO General Counsel David Silberman added (Daily Labor Report, June 5, 1985): The short of time matter‘ is that the principal responsibility for administering the Wagner Act has been entrusted to a man who is hostile to the fundamental purposes of the Act, and to labor organizations which seek to promote those aims. And under Mr. Dotson’s leadership the Labor Board has proceeded to systematically subvert the purposes of the law. Whether Dotson and the Board "subverted the purposes" of the law will be considered in the next chapter when doctrinal changes are reviewed. However, the evidence presented above indicates that the first half of 19803 were, indeed, turbulent years at the Board. From 1980 until 1983, conflicts involved mainly the appointment process as the Reagan administration took shape. Later, between 1983' and 1986, disagreements arose over major doctrinal changes. After 1986, things did calm a bit. First, the Republican Party lost control of the Senate, which meant that 67 Orrin Hatch yielded the chair of the Labor Committee to Edward Kennedy. There was an obvious impact on the appointment process as much more moderate individuals were put forward by the White House. In fact, conservative forces opposed the appointments of Chairman James Stephens and Member John Higgins (Daily Labor Report, December 21, 1987, A-7). But, moreover, there had been so many major reversals between 1983 and 1986, that there were very few areas of policy left to be disturbed. Therefore, the remaining years of the decade were relatively peaceful, with the Board seeing many of its decisions upheld by an increasingly conservative judiciary (Lansing and Podhajsky, 1990), which itself had been subject t1) an equally rigorous ideological reshaping. Goldman writes (1989, p. 319): The Reagan administration.was responsible for major innovathmns in the selection process [of federal judges] which endured throughout the two terms. The Office of Legal Policy was the locus of judicial selection activity. The screening process was systematized and for the first time III the history CHE judicial selection, all leading candidates for judicial positions were hmought to Washington for extensive interviewing by Justice Department personnel...Arguably, the Reagan administration was engaged in the most systematic judicial philos0phical screening of candidates ever seen in the nation’s history, surpassing Franklin Roosevelt’s administration. 68 One manifestation of this new system was that throughout Reagan’s entire presidency, not one Democrat gained an appointment to the Circuit Courts of Appeal. Not since the presidency of Warren G. Harding had the opposition party been passed over completely for such appointments. Further, the Circuits Courts are the first forum for the appeal of NLRB cases. However, because the federal court system is so many times larger than the Board, and appointments are for life rather than five year terms, change comes much more slowly. It was not until timeemmi of George Bush’s presidency that those appointed after the election of Reagan constituted a majority on the federal bench. Also, due to court practices and procedures, it is difficult to determine just how much of a "Reagan court effect" there may have been on labor relations decisions. Sometimes cases are heard by individual judges (who may or may not have been Reagan appointees), other times they are heard en banc, or by a committee of judges; cases may be heard in the circuit within which the dispute arose or e1sewhere——particularly in the District of Columbia Circuit; some judges eagerly apply precedents from other circuits, some do rmm” In short, there was almost certainly a shift toward a more conservative judiciary during the 1980s, the pmecise extent to vflfirfli it affected labor relations public policy is more difficult to determine 69 (Smith, 1993). E. conclusions. During the early to mid—1980s, the NLRB became the battleground for disputes over national labor policy to an extent not seen in four decades. The conflict was foreshadowed In! the chill ii1 relations Ibetween. top-level business and labor groups during the 19705 following, particularly, the failure of the Labor Law Reform .Act. Things became much worse, however, when the Reagan administration, with much encouragement from the Senate, cut organized labor out of the selection process and embarked on an ideological reordering of the Board. Selecting nominees with t:1‘1er terms and conditions of employment?" As the Supreme C: . . . CDIJJETt pOinted out in NLRB v. Insurance Agents International W (361 US 477, 485 (1960)), "[C]ongress was generally not (2 . . . . C>r1Cerned vnifli the substantive terms (x1 which time parties (:Cbtltlracted." Justice Brennan, the decision's author, went on thD quote Senator Wagner who had stated: When the employees have chosen their organization, when they have selected their representatives, all the bill proposes to do is to escort them to the door of their employer and say ’Here they are the legal representatives (ME your 73 employees.’ What happens behind those doors is not inquired into, and the bill does not seek to inquire into it (361 US 477, 484). While accepting the general philosophy of the Senator's sstéat:I'1t:_inued to hold that the government should, to the extent 1E><:’Ssssible, refrain from CMctating the substantive terms of negotiations. As the law developed, however, questions continued to arise. A couple of years before Insurance Agents, the SL1IDreme Court began developing a line of reasoning that would 1‘6361Ci eventually to a three part taxonomy of issues (NLRB v. 2332S1§ter Division of Borg Warner Corp., 356 US 342, (1958)). ISSues that have as their primary focus the employment rGalationship are mandatory subjects of bargaining and must be discussed if raised by either party (e.g work rules, IDEnsions, and benefits); issues that clearly violate the Act 74 or any other statutes are illegal subjects of bargaining and must: not be discussed at all (e.g. race—based work assignments, closed shop provisions); all other issues are permissive subjects of bargaining, and may be discussed by mutual consent of the parties. Today, there is not a great deal of controversy over i .1 legal subjects,1 but there are volumes of cases in which the parties have disagreed on whether an issue should be Classified as mandatory or merely permissive.2 The r“<31’1Ciatory/permissive distinction is an important one (Sockell and Delaney, 1986, Sockell, 1986, 1989). If a union raises X 1 An exception is the controversy over work preservation CJ~6l‘Lises (Hieb and Moody, 1981; Moon, 1987; Rappa, 1986; ROSenberg, 1984; Steffen, 1989; Zidich, 1984). In general, C lauses which preserve work are legal, but clauses designed to acquire work are not (National Woodwork Manufacturers Mciation v. NLRB 386 us 203, 1964). With changing aechnology, this distinction is not always easy to make. In S eries of Board and Supreme Court cases, it was determined :ha t- a provision in the Longshoremen’s Association’s contract w:quiring that its members unload ship containers in s i réhouses miles from shore was legal since the work done was Lomllar to the work ILA members had always done (International Whoremen’s Association v. NLRB (ILA I) 447 US 490 (1980); Wnational Longshoremen’s Association v. NLRB (ILA II) 973 DJ: 61 (1985)). A further issue could arise if a work .. eLaaervation clause appeared to be a illegal attempt at foeatherbedding." Unions can demand that employees be paid V unnecessary work, but not for doing no work at all (NLRB 1': Wmle Enterprises, Inc. 345 US 117 (1953)). 3 In most cases it is the union arguing that an issue <3 atgement sees as its sole prerogative to decide should be Casandatory subject of bargaining. But this is not always the mate - Sometimes employers Wish to bargain over internal union QQnCEIs, such as the procedure by which members ratify a tract; in fact, Borg Warner was one such case. man 75 a permissive issue—~say, the price a company charges for its product--the employer may simply refuse to discuss the subject without violating the law. Just as important, there is no obligation for either party to fulfill information requests, nor may the parties engage in strikes or lockouts over permissive issues. If a subject is mandatory, however, the parties must bargain and must provide each other with necessary information about the issue. Further, in the absence of an agreement an employer may implement a mandatory issue only after the parties have bargained to a bona fide impasse. And, finally, when dealing with a mandatory EsLllDject, the parties may reinforce their positions with St- rikes, lockouts, or other such pressure tactics (assuming no Contractual agreement to the contrary is in force) (Cox, 80k and Gorman, 1986) . The mandatory/permissive distinction becomes most (ii f ficult to apply in cases involving business decisions that a f f ect bargaining unit jobs or the bargaining unit itself: QJ‘Qsaing or relocating an establishment, investing in new t:eel’inology, or subcontracting unit work. The difficulty is QCDIT‘lDOunded when it is unclear whether a business decision is “IQ: i\fated by a labor issue, or is made simply in response to, Say . changing market conditions or the availability of new t_QQ1-'1riology. The critical question is, Does a business de - . Qlsions automatically involve a “term or condition or 76 employment" when it has a collateral effect on the bargaining unit and bargaining unit employment? Although this has never been an easy question to answer, during the 19805, and particularly between 1983 and 1986, the answer became more favorable to employers (Barton, 1986; Dube, 1986). 1. An employer's duty to bargain over business decisions affecting the bargaining unit. There are differences in substance between plant Closings and relocations, subcontracting, and technological SUbstitutions, but the legal issues concern the same point: leSt; an employer bargain over such decisions? As Gacek ( 1981) noted, legal reasoning in this area has developed along three lines. At times the Board and courts have at(jQEDt:ed a standard of "open bargaining," which offers a S t— rorig presumption in favor of mandatory decision—bargaining. At other times, such decisions have been considered presumptively "management rights" with a requirement only to bargain over the "effects" of a decision, but not the decision itself.3 And the third approach has been a pragmatic balancing of rights," where the benefits of be I gaining versus unilateral action are conSldered on a case- /\ 3 It must be noted that even when an employer has no mil lgation to bargain over a busmess deClSion, the employer uh . t- bargain over the effects of that decision on bargaining relt employees. Issues might include severance packages, hat— raining, outplacement assistance, etc. At least one author es questioned whether there is a meaningful difference t"Ween decision and effects bargaining (Kohler, 1983) . 77 by—case basis. Because of the differing and wavering positions of the Board, the Circuit Courts, and the Supreme Court on this iesssLie over the years, it is a very difficult area of law to :fc31_lxow (Gacek, 1981; George, 1985; Irving, 1982; Millspaugh, 1984; O’Connell, 1986). It is equally difficult to make g;ear1&en:al statements about what the law has been at any given CLignnee.. Frequently, different standards have been applied in C341 ffifeerent Circuits, and, at times, Board decisions seem to have contradicted even the Supreme Court. Nonetheless, if(DJ—lowing a series of mid—1980s Board decisions, the 1:>EiI-‘§3'aining mandate reached its narrowest point in the history (2’13 the Act (Ashford and Ayers, 1987; Barton, 1986; COliingswortn, 1993; Dube, 1986; Hedlund, 1986). Case law in this area began with Gerity Whitaker Company ( :3 :3 IqLRB 393 (1941)). In that case the Board determined that t:'171633 <:ompany had breached its duty to bargain with the Metal ‘E3<:)-1—ii¢shers Union when it unilaterally terminated operations in <:>r)”63 pdant and moved them to another. Five years later in ‘Zglé‘111125en Roller Bearing (70 NLRB 500 (1946)) the Board issued 51 EsJiInilar finding iii a subcontracting case. However, at €11:N:)\l . t the same time, the Board suggested that an employer C2<:)Lll<:1, perhaps, take a unilateral action that would terminate :3<:it353 so long as the employer was not doing so out of anti— \111‘ J‘CDYI animus (Pepsi Cola Bottling Company of Montgomery (72 78 rJLJRB 601 (1947)). When the Eisenhower Board was seated, it preferred the reasoning of Pepsi Cola to that of the earlier decisions (:seeea, for example, Bickford Shoes, 109 NLRB 1346 (1954)). ZAIICi in its final year before yielding to a Kennedy—appointed rnaa:ic>rity, the Board made one its most sweeping decisions in t:r1j.ss area. In Fibreboard Products Company Immx (130 NLRB -1—ESESE3 (1961)) the Board held that an employer had the right to tLEEJCITIinate all bargaining unit employees in favor of a Subcontractor without bargaining over the decision. The E3<3>Eiitxj distinguished the present case from earlier ones in E""]=-'7|-:3L<:l“1 the union would continue to represent remaining earnI:>J.rnr>éany (362 [K3 330 (1960)). While supporting mandatory Cieec::Lssion—bargaining, time Telegraphers case lumi been issued under the Railway Labor Act (45 USC 151) not the NLRA. -P1CDXA7€3\/er, in 1964 the Supreme Court granted certiorari in the -1:Zi.k31rweboard II case mentioned above (Fibreboard Products v. W 379 us 203 (1964)). The issue in Fibreboard was whether an employer could ‘LlliliL-luaterally subcontract bargaining unit work upon the EB:"(ISIM‘Lration of an agreement without first bargaining over the - Qrgaining (Gacek, 1981). 81 Shortly after Fibreboard II the Supreme Court returned to the issue of mandatory bargaining under a somewhat different set of facts. In Darlington Manufacturing v. NLRB (380 US 263 (1965)) the Court was presented with a case in which the employer had closed one of its facilities in response to a successful union organizing drive. The Board asked the Court to find the employer guilty of anti—union animus in its decision (a violation of NLRA, Section 8(a) (3)) and of a failure to bargain over the decision to close. The Court determined that, indeed, the company was in Violation of the Act, resting its decision on the key fact that. the Darlington plant was one of many owned by Deering Mi lliken of New York City. The Court accepted the NLRB’s View that in multi-plant situations the closing of a single J‘E<31Cility in response to an organizing victory could put a .. C1'1i11“ into union drives elsewhere, and was, therefore, the CYpe of behavior Section 8(a) (3) sought to proscribe.‘ The CQUrt largely skirted the duty to bargain issue, however, but did add that a complete shutdown of the firm would have Q1iatnged its decision entirely (380 US 263, 274): \ Co ‘ Some commentators have noted the irony of the Supreme Qlul‘t's concern about “the. potential impact on employees DaSevvhere, but relative indifference to the direct effects on Ehrlington workers. Clyde Summers wrote: "This is to see in Die execution of. hostages nothing more than an intimidation 1‘1 l the liVlng; it is to make murder a crime only when the lers purpose is to instill fear (Summers, 1965, p. 67)." 82 We hold that as far as the Labor Act is concerned, an employer has the absolute right to terminate his entire business for any reason he pleases. During this same period, several of the Circuit Courts were relying heavily on Justice Stewart’s Fibreboard dicta to create a presumption in favor of management’s unilateral right to make business decisions (see, for example, m Royal Plating and Polishing Company, 350 F.2d. 191 (1965); Adams Diary 350 F2d 108 (1965)). The Board, however, was heading in the opposite direction, and using Darlington as an argument for creating a presumption in favor of mandatory dec ision-bargaining over partial closings. This outcome is most obvious in the case of M W (161 NLRB 561 (1966)). Although Ozark was not C eCElfinically a multi—plant operation, the Board considered its CCDI”T‘IInon ownership with several other companies and the integrated nature of its operation in concluding that Ozark was a multi—plant operation "under the Act." Further, the Board gave very little weight to company's assertion that its mQVe had been made for solely economic reasons and focused, instead, on the impact on employees. In a sweeping philosophical statement, which deserves to be quoted at l eh91th, the Board wrote (161 NLRB 561 at 565): 83 With all respect to Court of Appeals for the Third and Eighth Circuit,5 we do not believe that the question of whether a particular management decisions must be bargained about should turn.cm1 whether the decision involves the commitment of investment capital or on whether it may be characterized as involving a ’major’ or ’basic' change in the nature of the employer’s Zbusiness. True i1: is that decisions of this nature are, by definition, of significance for the employer. It is equally true, however, and not tx> be lost sight cfifi that an employer's decision tx> make 51 'nejor' change ijl the nature cu? his business, such. as tflma termination. of 61 portion thereof, is also of significance for employees whose jobs will be lost by the termination. For just ems the employer has invested capital in the business, so the employee has invested years of his working life, accumulating seniority, accruing pension rights, and developing skills that may or may not be salable to another employer. And just as the employer’s interest in the protection of his capital investment is entitled to consideration 111 our interpretation of the Act, so too is the employee’s interest in the protection of his livelihood. In effect, the Board was creating a job right on par ‘VVTi—t:}1 an employer’s property right (O’Connell, 1986). It is IDITCDIDablynot surprising that the Circuit Courts generally had ‘tLITCDIihdtzwith this View (see, for example, NLRB V. Transmarine ESEEL“EC-iézation Company 308 F.2d. 933 (1967)). Further, when the IQ” . len Board was seated, it retreated from such a strong \ 5 E3<2> The Third and Eighth Circuits had refused to enforce 53133 orders in Royal Plating and Adams Dairy, respectively 84 bargaining presumption in a couple of noteworthy cases. In general Motors Corporation (191 NLRB 951 (1971)), the Board held that the sale of a retail business constituted a major Change in operations and was, therefore, not a mandatory subject. And, in Summit Toolinq (195 NLRB 479 (1972)), the Board came to a similar conclusion in a case involving a partial closing. But following Jimmy Carter's election, and the elevation Of John Fanning to chair, the Board resurrected its Ozark Trailer standards. In fact, in at least one case, the Board af f :ered6 an opinion that relied almost exclusively on Ozark Trailers and completely ignored General Motors and Summit TOOling (ABC Trans—National Transport Inc. 247 NLRB No. 25 ( 1980)). In other cases, the Board was more careful to raise, but then dismiss, the General Motors and Summit Tooling rationale (Midland—Ross Corporation, 239 NLRB 323 ( l 9'78); National Family Opinion, 246 NLRB No. 84 (1979)). In Brockway Motor Trucks v. NLRB (582 F2d 720, 1978) the Third Circuit was given the opportunity to review the issue of whether a partial closing was subject to mandatory decision-bargaining. Recall that the Ozark Trailer standards '\ 16:09te Aecording to Board procedures, if a charged party wishes to ab fOrQ a Regional Director’s decision, it is entitled to'a‘ trial 1% an Administrative Law Judge. If the ALJ’s dec151on 18 to the full Board, the Board may simply affirm it without COInment, as was done in this case. ea furthgr 85 vveare developed in the breach: the Board had used a Supreme (:cnart decision stating that total closings were not subject t;c) Inandatory bargaining to create a presumption that partial Brockway the Circuit Court refused Cl osings were. In eeriifcarcement on technical grounds——the Board had not presented facts on the case——but went on to jgt vvith sufficient sgaee<2111ate about what the standards for mandatory bargaining iii SSLJCh cases might be. Most notably, the Court stated that tldeezfee should be a presumption in favor of bargaining unless t:k1€2 eemployer is in dire economic straits and quick decisions must; be made, some third party action has already made .kDEiIIngéiining fruitless, or bargaining would jeopardize pending r1e§Jl”‘npany. The Second Circuit Court enforced the Board’s Order, but called into question its per se standard, derived f rom Ozark Trailers, that partial closings were a mandatory ESkllsject of bargaining. Instead, the Court suggested a 1Telbuttable presumption in favor of bargaining that could be Qvércome if strong enough mitigating circumstances were found ( 627 F2d 569, (1980)). The Supreme Court, with Justices Marshall and Brennan dissenting, overturned both the Board and the Second Circuit. It ruled that a management decision, if its purpose was "apart from the employment relationship" was a mandatory a . L113ject of bargaining only when it can be shown that the 87 benefil:s to labor—management relations émui the collective bargairiirmz process outweigh the burden. to the employer. Applyiiig that rationale to the case at hand, it found that a decisix:n.to close part of a business was beyond the scope of mandatrary bargaining (452 US 666 (1981)). Jiistice Blackmun, writing for the majority, stated that the dexoision of the employer (452 US 666, 677), had a direct impact on employment, since jobs are inexorably' eliminated 13/ the termination, but had as its focus only the economic profits of the contract with Greenpark, a concern under fact wholly apart from the employment relationship. This decision is akin tt)ea decision of whether to be in business at all. Iiea then wrote (452 US 666, 679): In view of an employer’s need for unencumbered decision making, bargaining over :management decisions that have (a substantial impact on the continued availability of employment should be required only if the benefit, for labor— management relations and the collective bargaining process, outweighs the burden placed on the conduct of the business. Paid in applying such criteria to the FNM case, he ccwuzltujed (452 US 666, 686): [T]he harm likely to be done to the employer and an employer’s need to operate freely' in. deciding ‘whether to shut down part of its business purely for economic reasons outweighs the incremental benefit that might be gained through the union’s participation in making the decision; and we hold that the decision itself is not part of 8(d)’s terms and conditions over which Congress 88 has mandated bargaining. One cuirtious aspect of the Court’s decision is that it, at first, :recommends a balancing test, but rather than allowing this teest to be conducted on a case—by—case basis, concludes \Nith ea new lper se standard against mandatory decision— bargaquing in partial closing cases (Somson, 1984). 'True FNM decision was a Rejor reversal of doctrine and resultxed.:u1 the immediate dismissal of scores of partial Closing cases. However, General Counsel Lubbers, in his menmnaarida to the NLRB regional offices, urged a very careful reading of the FNM decision. In particular he focused on Footrnot:e 22 (452 US 666, 686), which states: In this opinion we of course intimate no view as to other types of management decisions, such as plant relocations, sales, other kinds of subcontracting, automation, etc. which. are t1) be considered on their particular facts. In Iliss Memoranda to Regional Directors, the General Counsel wrtflle (Lubbers, 1981, p. E-l).: [T]he Court expressly limited its holding in First National Maintenance to economicallyr motivated.(decisions tx> go partially (mm; of hmsiness. The Court stated that it intimated no view as to other types of management decisions, such as plant relocations, sales, subcontracting, automation, etc. ...Thus, for example, decisions to relocate a plant, to subcontract, to eliminate unit jobs through automation, or to consolidate operations are not akin to a decision whether to be in business at all. That is, the employer does not 89 intend to withdraw from the business activity, either wholly or partially. Instead the employer intends to remain in the same business, albeit elsewhere (relocation), or through the use of subcontractors (subcontracting), or with different equipment (automation) (n: at one location rather than several (consolidation). .. If the factors which indicate that time decision if; amenable tc> the process of collective bargaining clearly outweigh the factor that indicate that bargaining would be ’burdensome’ to the decision-making employer, the Region should issue 61 complaint. This result would be consistent to Board law prior to First National Maintenance. TTue Lubbers guidelines may have blunted the full effects of Firmst:.National Maintenance for several years. The Board contirniexi to order bargaining routinely in cases of relocatixon, subcontracting, and technological change. But When thee Reagan Board was in place (following Member Dennis’s SWearirug-—in on May 5, 1983) mandatory bargaining was severely limited :in.these other areas as well. The Board effected this Change vvilih a reversal of its 1981 decision in Otis Elevator (225 N1J{E3 235, 1981). The new Board asked for the case back While tlaee company’s petition for review' and. the ZBoard’s DEtitiOrl ‘for enforcement stood before the D.C. Circuit Court (296 NLRB 891, 1984). IT“? <:ompany, a division of United Technologies, sought to (“NHSCXLidate its New Jersey operations with operations in C01) . . nectJ—Cut. The move would have ended a collective 9O bargairring relationship with the United Auto Workers which represented some of the New Jersey workers. The company claimemi that the consolidation was a major capital decision and, truerefore, beyond the scope of bargaining, but the Board had dishagreed and ordered the company to bargain. .Affl:er achieving remand, the Dotson Board reversed the earlier‘ decision. As evidence of the difficulties in this case, tliree separate decisions were handed down by the four sitting) Board members (Member Jenkins’s vacated seat had yet to be fiilled). Chairman Dotson and member Hunter formed the pluralcit§/, and in their decision wrote that Otis’s move (296 NLRB 891. at 893), turned upon a fundamental change in the nature and direction of business, and for that reason is excluded from the limited area of bargaining described by 8(d) (my emphasis). They contrinued (296 NLRB 891 at 894): Despite time evident effect on employees, the critical factor to a determination whether the decision is subject to mandatory bargaining is the essence of the decision itself, i.e. whether it turns upon a change in the nature or direction of the business, or turns upon labor costs; not its effect on employees nor the union’s ability to offer concessions.7 An ‘ . . . d‘1J1 Language clearly aimed at the Lubbers Guidelines (269 NLRB 891 at 894) \— 7 COI“pare this language to Ozark Trailers above. 91 Such decisions include, inter alia, decisions tx) sell ea business cm (a part thereof, t1) dispose cfif its assets, to restructure or consolidate operations, to subcontract, tt) invest iii labor-saving machinery, to change the methods of finance or of sales, advertising, product design, and all other decisions akin to the forgoing (my emphasis). Urnjer the plurality’s rationale, unless a business decisixanq in an increasingly limited number of areas, "turned upon" lxabor costs, the issue was not a mandatory subject of bargairring regardless of its impact on the bargaining unit or unit jcibs. Members Dennis and Zimmerman urged a less restricfi:ive standard that would have allowed unions a role in discmunsiiig a broader range of economic issues (although Dennis st:ill felt that the burden remained on the union to Show tluat: an issue should be bargained). Dotson and Hunter were IKJC persuaded. The Ckis rationahe was adopted and represeuiteed the narrowest view of bargaining ever advanced by the Boarci, FUIWllier, the CMis rationale was quickly spread by the B . . . Card to 51 number of other areas (see, in addition to those di . . . . scusseci below, Columbra City Freight Lanes 3TWL NLRB 12 (1984); gigaser shipyard 272 NLRB 496 (1984); Boetrem D' ' - ‘£!$§ASELL_JQOR, Inc. 272 NLRB 999 (1984); Kroger Co. 273 NLRB 46 . 2 (19854)). For example, in the subcontracting case Gar WOO . .iiiiLLEflggggig (274 NLRB 23, 1985), a Dotson/Hunter plurality 92 decidexi that the company’s action, although not unlike many previCNJS subcontracting cases, («n5 undertaken 'Wxi prevent econondx: chaos," and was, therefore, not amenable to resoltu:ion through bargaining. Sijnilarly, the Board’s rationale with regard to technological substitution also changed. In one of its earlixest; cases in this area, Renton News (136 NLRB 1294 at 1297 (1A962)) the Board wrote: [T]he impact of automation on a specific category of employees is a matter of grave concern to them. It may involve not only their present but future employment in the skills for which the have been trained. Accordingly, the effect of automation on employment is a joint responsibility of employers and the representatives of employees. TTMe Board continued this Jaime of reasoning an: least through. 16982. In the case of Plymouth Locomotive (261 NLRB 87 at 88 (1982)), it stated: Where the automation of bargaining unit work will result in the elimination of unit jobs, it is the chnaz of the employer to bargain with its employees’ representative over the decision to install automated equipment, as well as the effects of such a decision. HoweVer, in the 1985 case of Central Broadcastinq (280 NL . RB 56' 1985), the Board was careful to note that the CO 0 v ' mpany violated the Act by requing to bargain over the eff . . . em3ts (If its decision to automate, not the deCiSion itself. The . ‘Boalki’s post—Otis position on technological change 93 prompted Sockell to write (1993, p. 62): By keeping technology out of the joint control of the union and management, those who shape public policy have emasculated the role of the union in the firm, a role the law has continued to shrink over time. 2. Moving work during the life of an agreement. The role of the union within the firm was further diminished when the Board removed the union’s ability to resist mid—term movements of bargaining unit work. In the cases mentioned above, the issue in dispute had been whether an employer needed to bargain to impasse over a decision to eliminate bargaining unit work, usually upon expiration of an agreement. In the case of Milwaukee Spring Division of Illinois Coil Spring Co. v. UAW (265 NLRB 206 (1982), the question concerned an employer’s ability to move work during the life of an agreement in order to avoid paying UHiOH wages. For a number of years, the Board had held that an employer could not move work from a union to a nonunion f ' ' . . . aCllltY during the life of a contract Without the consent of th ' . . - e union if the obVious purpose of the move was to aVOid a r ' - . . p OVlSlOn of the collective bargaining agreement (Bosanac, 1983; I . . ' rVing, 1983). To move work mid—term Without the unio I ‘ . . n S Consent had been conSidered a unilateral change in Vic) - latiOn of Section 8(d) . 94 Ekarlier Boards had extended the 'WK) movement without agreenuent" standard by relying on the "recognition clause" presern: :ni most labor contracts. The typical recognition clausea states that the employer recognizes the union’s right to repnresent a specified group of employees. To move work to indivixiuals not covered by the recognition clause constiizuted, in the Board’s view, a unilateral change. This broad :reeding of such clauses was not given very favorable reviemms by the courts. The Seventh Circuit, in the case of Univeresity of Chicago v.. NLRB (514 F.2d. 942 (1975)) overturuied the Board, and stated (514 F.2d. 942, 949): [U]nless transfers are specifically prohibited by the bargaining agreement, an employer is free to transfer work out of the bargaining unit if: 1) the employer complies with Fibreboard Paper Products v. NLRB, by bargaining in good faith to impasse; and 2) the employer is not motivated by anti-union animus, [as is] Textile Workers v. Darlington. 3T“? iNinth Circuit, however, enforced the Board’s order in a Geese; in which it was able to prove that an employer had m . . . . OVQd WCXr1< a short distance to aVOid paying union wages (Los A . Wrine Hardware v. NLRB, 602 F.2d. 1302 (1979)). So . . on afilEtr, the Board had an opportunity to apply its Los An . . ~ - - geles Marine rationale to a case ariSing back in the Seventh (Zircuit. MilWaukee Spring Company was a division of Illinois Coil Spr ' . 1ngCOrporation, which owned several plants. both union ¥ 95 and non—union. In 1982 the company asked UAW Local 547, which represented workers at the Milwaukee division, to reopen its contract, particularly with regard to the wage schedule. The company pointed out that Milwaukee workers were earning almost twice as much as workers at its nonunion facilities. The parties bargained to impasse, but the union voted down the company’s final proposal. The company responded by closing the Milwaukee facility and shifting work to McHenry Spring, a nonunion subsidiary. The union filed an unfair labor practice which the Board upheld based on its Los Angel es Marine rationale. When the Board’s majority changed, however, it asked the Seventh Circuit to remand the case to it for reconsideration, and in Milwaukee Spring II (268 NLRB 601 (1984)) overruled the prior decision. Although the earlier Board had been careful to distinguish this case from University of Chicago, Whieh involved a performance issue not wages, the Dotson Board held that the Seventh Circuit’s reasoning in University Of Chicago not the Ninth Circuit’s reasoning in Los Angeles Marine should be controlling. DOtson, Hunter, and Dennis determined that in order for an . . L11'1fair labor practice to stand, the Board would have to fi . . nd a specific clause relating to the relocation of work th . at had been violated. They did not believe that the wage c a , , , L‘lSae had been altered by the company in this case, arguing 96 that: t:11e payment of nonunion wages at McHenry did nothing to charngte the wages at Milwaukee——even though, as Member Zinunexrrnan pointed out in his dissent, there were no workers left; .iii Milwaukee to be paid according to the union scale! Efirrtlieary the Board rejected the idea that recognition clauses deserved the broad reading earlier Boards had given them. iiueree \Nere contracts that contained actual work preservation clatusees, and in their absence, the Board held, they should not be inferred. IIri his dissent, Member Zimmerman focused (M1 the wage provisions. His frustration was obvious (268 NLRB 601 at 606) : It is disingenuous to argue, as do my colleagues, that [Milwaukee Spring’s] relocation. did run: disturb the contractual wages and benefits of the Milwaukee facility. If [Milwaukee Spring] had implemented its decision, there would be no assembly employees at the Milwaukee facility to receive the contractual wages and. benefits...Under these circumstances, my colleagues’s conclusion that [Milwaukee Spring] left the wage and benefits provision ’intact’ at Milwaukee is illogical and without legal significance. T - . . . . he Circuit Court for the District of Columbia, however, ac . . . . . CEeDtZed the majority’s View and the Seventh Circuit’s StéiIICLard became Board doctrine (765 F. 2d~ 179' 1985): 97 c- The loss of certification. 1. Questions of majority support. As the model of union disappearance in Equation 1 shows, wi thout any of the types of business decisions outlined above occurring, a relationship ends if the union loses its right to represent bargaining unit workers. Typically this loss would occur through a decertification election—~either an employee-initiated RD election or an employer-initiated RM e1 ection‘-—held under Section 9 of the Act. Alternatively, an employer may simply repudiate the relationship based on a good faith doubt that the union continues to enjoy the support of a majority of unit members, or a union may simply give up its right of representation (usually when facing Certain decertification). The basic procedures in this area of law are statutory, and , therefore, have not changed since 1947. A deCertification election occurs much like a certification e1ection. First, the Board must receive a petition indicating that at least thirty percent of bargaining unit Inertfibers seek an election. Once this "showing of interest" is established, an election like any other is held. The union mus t receive majority support to continue as bargaining epresentative. A tie vote goes against the union Since Vldence of majority support would be lacking. Since a QCEertification election occurs much like a certification 98 election, the standards of election conduct are germane to both situations. Employers have always been precluded from initiating an employee decertification petition (Pierce, 1982). However, since it is a violation of the Act for employers to deal with an organization that does not have the support of a majority of bargaining unit members, there are ways for employers to push the certification question (Flynn, 1991; Schupp, 1991).8 Employers may simply refuse to bargain or may petition the NLRB for an RM election. To forestall the tactical use of either of these tests, the Board and courts insist that employers have some evidence to support a "good faith doubt" of a union’s status (Texas Petrochemicals, 296 NLRB 139, 1989). Case law suggests that employers are on the safest footing when they can produce several separate pieces of evidence—-copies of letters of resignation from (former) union members, proof of the union’s inability to maintain a slate (HE officers (Bickerstaff Clay FToducts \J. NLRB 371 F.2d. 980 (1989)), and employees' letters indicating dissatisfaction with union representation (AMBAC _nternational and Engineers Local 112, 299 NLRB No. 66 ° This point needs some clarification. An employer and minority union may agree to a "members~only“ pact, but cannot enter into éni agreement CHI behalf of and. bargaining unit members. Since an employer has absolutely no legal obligation to meet with a minority union, such agreements are very rare, although a few exist in the needle trades (Gould, 1993). 99 (1990)). Employers may also conduct a secret ballot poll of workers, but only as a confirmatory measure (Mingtree Restaurant 265 NLRB 409 (1982)). The law merely requires good faith doubt, not ironclad proof. However, if the Board finds that a union, contrary to an employer’s belief, maintains majority support, the employer could be found guilty of failing to bargain and be required to reverse or remedy any unilateral action that may have been taken. The question of majority status often occurs after the transfer of business ownership or, more frequently, after a strike when replacement workers have been used. In the former case, if and when a former owner’s employees constitute a majority of bargaining unit members with a "successor employer," the successor is required to begin dealing with the union (Fall River Dyeing and Finishing 482 US 27 (1987)). Of course, due to changes in operations that often accompany a transfer of ownership, this standard is not always easy to apply. The latter issue, strike replacements, has created even more controversy. At one time, the Board presumed that replacement workers continued to support the union (Peoples EELS System, Inc. 214 NLRB 944 (1974)). Later, the Board Concluded that replacement workers supported the union in the Same proportion as striking workers (Windham Community 100 Memorial Hospital, 230 INLRB 1070 (1977)). However, the First, Fifth and Eighth Circuits chose to adopt the views of Professor Robert Gorman who, in a legal treatise on the subject, argued that it was illogical to presume that replacements continued t1) support the infirni (National Car Rental v. NLRB, 594 F.2d. 1203 (1979); Soule Glass & Glazing Co v. NLRB 652 F.2d. 1055 (1981); NLRB v. Randel-Eastern Ambulance Service, Inc. 584 F. 2d. 720 (1978)). Finally, in Buckley Broadcasting (284 NLRB 1339 (1987)) the Board took a middle road and opted for a no presumption rule. Although Buckley was a retreat from the earlier, stronger presumption of support, the Board did not go so far as to adopt the Gorman presumptions. To resolve the conflict between several of the Circuits, and between the Board and the Circuits, the Supreme Court granted certiorari in Curtin Matheson Scientific (110 5341:. 1542 (1990) and, in.ea 5—4 vote, upheld the Board’s no presumption rule. At least one scholar (Leroy, 1991) has found empirical support for the new standard. There are consequences arising from this new standard. Since there is no longer a presumption°ir1favor of the union, it would seem that an employer's good faith doubt maintains \ 9 When there has been no replacement of workers, a union Still enjoys a rebuttable presumption of support, and an irrebuttable presumption for the 12 months following a CErtification election (Cox, Bok, and Gorman, 1987). 101 equal standing with a union’s assertion of continued support. In such an environment, a union’s ability to stem defections seems especially critical. However, that ability was also eroded in several mid-1980s cases. 2. Onion discipline. When time Act ku5 amended lIl 1947, Congress included within it a set of union unfair labor practices to mirror the Wagner Act's employer unfair labor practices, Section 8(b). The first of these, Section 8(b)(1)(A), makes it an unfair labor practice for a union, "to restrain or coerce employees in the exercise of the rights guaranteed in section 7." The section continues, however: [T]his paragraph shall not impair the right of a labor organization to prescribe its own rules with respect to the acquisition or retention of membership...“ It was the preceding language that guided the Supreme Court in its seminal union discipline case, NLRB v. Allis— Chalmers Manufacturing Co. (388 US 175 (1967)). In that case, the Court held that a union could fine a member for crossing a.picket line and returning to work during a strike, and could sue in state court to collect the fine. The dissenters in the case noted that Section 8(b)(1)(A) speaks only of a union’s right to promulgate rules "with respect to the acquisition and retention.of membership," not picket line crossing; The Court was not persuaded, and spoke of how majority rule was at the 102 "heart of federal labor policy" and that, "the power to fine or expel strikebreakers is essential if the union is to be an effective bargaining agent." It. is extremely' important to ‘note that the Supreme Court%3 decision jjl Allis—Chalmers applied only t1) union members. A union may not fine bargaining unit employees who are not union members. This issue arose in NLRB v. Textile Workers Local 1029, Granite State Joint Board (409 US 213 (1972)). Several months into a strike, several dozen members resigned from the Textile Workers Union and went back to work. The union attempted to fine each member $2000 pursuant to a resolution. passed. concurrent vulji the strike ‘vote. The Supreme (Rmnfig however, refused Ix) uphold (flue discipline stating that "the union has no more control over a former a member that it does over the man in the street (409 US 213, 217)." Justice Douglas noted that "neither the contract nor the Union's constitution or bylaws contained any provision defining or linnting'tflue circumstance under ukfirfliea member could resign (409 US 213, 214)." A year later the Supreme Court held that a union’s constitutional clause prohibiting strikebreaking was not enough to allow it to levy a fine against a former member because, once again, the union’s Constitution was silent on the issue of resignation (Booster Lque No. 405 v. NLRB, 412 US 84 (1973)). In response to both decisions, many unions began 103 promulgating rules governing resignations (Oliver, 1986). Some unions, however, exceeded the standard of reasonableness in, their‘ pre—conditions for‘ resignation, and. found. their guidelines voided by the Board. A sixty-day waiting period, for example, was thrown out by the Board in General Electric Co. (197 NLRB 608 (1972)). And in Dalmo Victor (231 NLRB 719 (1977)), the Board found the Machinists’ Union in violation of the Act when it tried to fine an ex—member who had crossed a picket line because he had not resigned at least fourteen days before the strike began in accordance with the union's constitution. In the Board’s view, the union’s action was an unlawful attempt to control the behavior of a former member. It further expressed its displeasure with limits on resignations linked specifically to times of strikes, which, the Board argued, would be when members would most want to resign. The Ninth Circuit disagreed with the Board, however, and refused enforcement in Dalmo Victor. (kiremand, the Board fashioned.a compromise, which allowed for a thirty day waiting period on resignations, so long as it applied both during strikes and otherwise (Dalmo Victor II, 263 NLRB 984, 1982). Chairman Van De Water and Member Hunter dissented in the opinion, questioning the rationale that went into the selection of "thirty" as the appropriate number of days. When the Reagan Board was seated the matter was settled With the adoption of a very clear standard. Unions could 104 promulgate IND rules restricting' the :right cflf members to resign. In Machinists Local 1414 (270 NLRB 1330 (1984)) the Board relied upon the Supreme Court’s holding in Scofield v. NLRB (394 US 423 (1969)), which stated that union discipline could not contradict national labor policy, to find restrictions on resignations in violation of an individual’s Section 7 right to "refrain from" collective activity. At about the same time, the Seventh Circuit was considering a case involving a charge by the Board against a Patternmakers’ rule restricting resignations during strikes (NLRB v. Patternmakers League of North America, 724 F2d 57, 1983), and the Ninth Circuit was examining the Board’s action in Dalmo Victor II. Tb smmtle matters, the Supreme Court granted certiorari and, in.a 5—4 decision accepted the Board’s view that all restrictions on resignations were unlawful (Patternmakers League of North America v. NLRB, 473 US 95 (1985)). In a sharp dissent, Justice Blackmun (writing also for Justices Brennan and Marshall) stated (473 US 95, 117): Today the Court supinely defers to a divided-vote determination by the National Labor 1Relations Board. that 23 union commits an unfair labor practice when it enforces a worker’s promise to his fellow workers not to resign from his union and return to work during a strike, even though the worker freely made the decision to join the union and freely made the promise not to resign at such a time, and even though union members AVA. vo-v \ Ar ..g,’ H- . . . i . .s u. . hv ~x~ r V: ,\& hks .. .3 . ( . . 9A 105 democratically made the decision to strike in full awareness of that promise. Since adoption of the standard, the Board and the Circuit Courts have extended the proscription regarding resignations in.aa number CHE cases (Communicatrmn Workers, Local 9201, 275 rHJHB 1529 (1985); Newspaper Guild Ci 1km) EggrkL Local 31, (1984); International Association of Iaachinist, Local 1769, (1984)). And in NLRB v. Sheet Metal Eggrkers Local 73, the Seventh Circuit even extended the rule tr) cover members already facing union discipline. Phenceforth, a member facing discipline need only resign to enscape the union's penalty. 3. Standards of conduct during' decertification elections. With less recourse against dissident members, unions may eru3CNJnter increasing' decertification activity. Mbre information about the extent of decertification elections Wilhl be provided in the next chapter. Here, the important issnnres concern the behavior of employers during the election prcuzeess. In Chapter II, it was noted that employer behavior durirlgcertification elections is advanced by several experts as 51 leading cause of union decline (Weiler, 1983; Freeman and Medoff, 1984; Freeman, 1989, 1989a, 1989b). or course, bOtfln. {marties have been known to engage in egregious conduct dulriJflgg elections, but an employer’s actions are, for obvious re . . . . . aSons, geared toward aVOiding or escaping a bargaining 106 relationship and are, therefore, more salient to this discussion. As mentioned above, since certification and decertification elections follow similar procedures, standards of election conduct are relevant to both situations. At the same time that Congress passed into law the sections of the Act regarding decertification (Section 9), it also passed Section 8(c) which guarantees employers free speech rights during election proceedings so long as employers make "no threat of reprisal or force or promise of benefit." Section 8(c) was designed to change the Board’s Wagner Act standard, which precluded employers’ involvement in elections altogether. The Board’s original reasoning was that the selection of a bargaining representative was strictly a matter for employees, and of no legitimate concern t<1) employers. Congress disagreed, however, and gave employers the right to intervene in the election process. Nonetheless, it was still the Board’s policy to maintain "laboratory" conditions for representation elections——whether they be certification elections or, as here, decertification eleCtions (General Shoe, 77 NLRB 124 (1948)). However, the Board also recognized that elections did not, in fact, "occur in a laboratory where controlled or artificial conditions may b . . . . e Established." Rather, it determined that it must gauge be . . . . . . havlor "in light of realistic standards of human behaVior 107 (Liberal Market, 108 NLRB 1481 (1954))." Over (flue years, tine permissible "standards cfif human behavior" lunna wavered. th‘ example, 111 Standard—Coosa- Thatcher (85 NLRB 1358 (1949)) the Board adopted a strong standand prohibiting tine interrogation (ME employees about their union sympathies. But the Eisenhower Board moved away from this standard several years later in Blue Flash Express (109 NLRB 591 (1954)) when it held that an interrogation may be lawful if there were no threats or promises made. Soon this standard was upended as well (Marsh Express, 140 NLRB 899 (1963); Laney Tank Lines 166 NLRB 1053 (1967)). But in 1973 and 1974, the Board decided to permit the questioning of "known union sympathizers" (B.F. Goodrich 201 NLRB 353 (1973); Stumpf Motor Company 208 NLRB 431 (1974); Federal Paper Board 206 NLRB 681 (1974)). But, still again, this lenient standard was changed in ITT Automotive (231 NLRB 878 (1977). And tine Board. finally cumma full circle 111 PPG Industries (251 NLRB 1146 (1980)) when it stated that interrogations were inherently coercive and were to be considered a per se violation of the Act. The interrogation standard was in obvious trouble when the Reagan Board began taking shape. Member Hunter and Chairman Dotson both dissented in interrogation cases earlier in their terms (Donnelly Manufacturing Company, 265 NLRB No. 196 (1982); Lambrecht Earth Movers, 267 NLRB No. 35 (1983). -1. s.. C. «\C 108 And, when Member Dennis finally joined the Board, the three were able to gain a majority, with Member Zimmerman dissenting, iji reversing lfiX? and remurning tt>ea standard closer to Eflue Flash (Rossmore House 269 NLRB 198 (1984). Following Rossmore House the Board routinely found interrogations lawful (Sears anmi Roebuck ~274 IHJHS No. 2 (1985); Michael's IMarket CM? Canterbury' 274 iNLRB It). 105 (1985); Diversified Products 272 NLRB No. 162 (1984)). The same type of oscillation can be seen in the Board’s standards concerning the misrepresentation of facts during an election campaign. The Board has reversed itself three times in determining that it would, then would not, then would, then would not set aside an election when it received evidence that one of the parties had made false statements (Hollywood Ceramics 140 NLRB 221 (1962); Shopping Kart Food Market 228 NLRB 1311; General Knit of California 239 NLRB 749 (1978); Midland National Life Insurance, 263 NLRB 127 (1982)). The Reagan Board also loosened the standard on what would and would not be regarded as threatening or coercive speech by an employer. The Board held that an employer could cite "economic realities" based on "objective fact." So, fOr example, employers could make insinuations concerning plant Closings, etc. if they could point to a unionized facility which. had, indeed, closed. Similarly, the Board began 109 allowing employers to rmflue such statements as "bargaining begins from zero (Pilliord of Mississippi, Inc. 275 NLRB No, 117 (1985))," or "bargaining begins from scratch (Atlantic Forest Products, 282 NLRB No. 105 (1987))." Both are obvious references to what could happen to one’s pay or benefits if union. representatitnl was chosen, tun: neither (would, henceforth, be considered threats under Section 8(c). Although these standards were adopted in response to certification campaigns, there is 1M3 reason vflur the same degree (ME latitude would rm»: be afforded employers during decertification proceedings as well. The complete record obviously shows that there have been significant changes over the years——even before the Reagan years--in all cflftflue legal principles cited» However, as Sockell and Delaney (1987. L1. 28) argue, "the Reagan NLRB decisions involve nwre tjmni the cyclical changes 1J1 NLRB policy that have accompanied. the agency’s shifting partisanship." The Reagan Board undertook a massive deregulation consistent with its broader agenda. Sockell and Delaney conclude, "The changes documented in this paper [concerning election conduct] represent only the tip of the iceberg...the overall pattern reflects an ideology that collective bargaining is not a valuable institution in society (p. 42)." 110 D. canclusions. The purpose of this chapter has been to explore some of the leading reversals of labor relations policy germane to the model of local union disappearance. Hence, it was shown that the Otis Elevator‘ standard. whittled the bargaining obligation over business decisions to its narrowest point in 'history by extending the Supreme Court’s rationale in First National Maintenance to most all management actions, including subcontracting and technological substitution. Further, in .Milwaukee Spring' II the Board decided that employers could move work during the life of a contract, even if to avoid a provision of a labor agreement, so long as there was 1x3 specific language 111 the contract (x) prevent them from doing so. The effects of both cases may have been to lower the costs associated with actions ending the bargaining' relationship kn! marginalizing' the Ixflja of the union within the firm, giving the employer more freedom to act, and allowing the union less opportunity to pursue self— preservation. In addition, the Board and courts have made it more difficult for unions to maintain their internal strength by voiding or eroding most forms of union discipline. The Machinists and Patternmakers cases outlawed rules limiting resignations, while the Sheetmetal WOrkers case extended the proscription to include members already facing discipline. lll Taken together, these cases leave unions with almost no power to enforce standards of member conduct. Maintaining union status against a threat of decertification may also have been. made more difficult. Buckley Broadcasting removed a more favorable presumption of union support on the part of replacement workers, but, more important, Midland.National Life, Rossmore House, Pilliord of Mississippi and their many progeny have, in effect, deregulated the election process. Several years ago Kenneth Gagala (1983) wrote a bmck entitled Union Organizing and Staying Organized. Roomkin and Block (1981), Weiler (1983) and many others have demonstrated how difficult organizing can be in the face of employer opposition and anemic legal protections. The changes of the mid—1980s may have made staying organized more difficult as well. And as International Typograhpical Union President J. Woodruff Randolph said in 1949, "The first and most important objective of any trade union is to stay alive (Tomlins, 1985, pp. 310-311)." Chapter V. Independent variables and Hypotheses. A. Introduction. In this chapter, my focus shifts from labor relations policy to a more general examination of the variables contained in the model of local union disappearance—~plant closings, relocations, input substitutions, and loss of certification. One section if; devoted to time first three topics, another to the decertification question. The purpose here is twofold: I examine trends in the variables during the period (fl? study. But 1: alas look (13 prior research to consider the role that anti—union (or anti—bargaining) motivations played in these trends. (Although in the case of decertification, the answer is obvious). Examining the latter point aids hypotheses generation. I would expect that a "pro—business" change in public policy would have the greater impact on phenomena more clearly linked to deunionization in the first place. Ftu‘ example, if employers have shown a willingness to relocate in order to escape unionization, then making that practice less troublesome may encourage it even more. On the other hand, if there :hs only ea weak ljmfi: between, swan technological improvement and union avoidance, changes in bargaining 112 113 obligations should have a less profound impact on the association between technological change and unit disappearance. Based on previous research, relocation seems most strongly tied to issues of unionization. The link is less certain with subcontracting and, particularly, technological change. And although it is possible, due to new standards in bankruptcy law, that some number of complete firm failures have been associated.with a desire to escape unionization, it is unlikely that rmnu/ employers lumna gone (mm: of business simply to avoid unionization. The loss of certification is almost certainly associated with a desire to escape unionization. B. Business decisions affecting the bargaining unit. 1. Plant closings. Of all the variables in the model, plant closings have received the most public and scholarly attention. Although the ‘problem is run: rmwm its sudden increase «during the recession of the early 19808 produced.a(groundswell of concern for displaced workers and devastated communities, as well as increased frustrations over what seemed to be an inadequate government response (Buss and Redburn, 1987). By the early 1980s, a number of states, and eventually the federal government considered or passed legislation dealing with some aspect of the problem (Krotsen, 1984; Rothstein, 1986). 114 (Currently federal laW' :requires employers t1) provide notification to their employees of their intention to close (29 USC 2101). An early and highly influential work on the plant closing issue is Bluestone and Harrison’s The Deindustrialization of America (1982), though many others have followed (see, for example, nmnographs 137 Howlamd, 1988; Perrucci, Perrucci, Targ, and Targ, 1988; Portz, 1990; Rothstein, 1986; Wendling, 1984). The information reported in these works and by the federal government is indeed compelling. 131a 1987 study, the Senate Human Resources Committee (U.S. Senate, 1987) revealed that almost 12 percent of labor force participants lost their jobs between 1981 and 1985 due to closings, with roughly 5 million. businesses-—about 2%) percent of 6UJ. businesses—— shutting down during the period. If the number of permanently laid-off individuals (from firms still in business) are added to those who lost their jobs due to closings, the numbers become even more staggering. The General Accounting Office (1986) reported that nearly 20 percent of workers lost their jobs due to plant closings or permanent layoffs in 1983 and 1984 alone. When Bluestone and Harrison examined the issue in 1982, the worst was yet to come. Returning to the theme in a recent work, Barry Bluestone and his father Irving (1992, p. 66) write: 115 By 1987, employment in manufacturing was actually lower than 111 1966..;Nearly a quarter of tflua producthmn workforce in the auto industry in 1978 would disappear by 1989; similarly' more than Ihalf <3f those who build farm machinery and construction equipment disappeared from these industries in the course of a single decade. In furniture, glass products, steel, metal products, machinery, food and beverages, textiles, clothing, paper, chemical products, and leather, employment fell below levels achieved ill the 1960s enmi 1970s. The distressing consequences of plant closings on workers, their families, and their communities were all too evident in terms of unemployment, income loss, and physical and mental trauma. Community impact was greatest in single company or single industry' towns (Buss eumi Redburn, 1983), but the effects (M1 particular' groups cflf workers are 51 bit less certain. Hamermesh (1989, p. 52) writes that, "Displacement is more likely among men then among women; among blacks and Hispanics‘ than among non-Hispanic whites; and especially among manufacturing workers." However, he also notes that contradictory findings are» common. Ftn: example, (Gordus, Jarley, and Ferman (1981) suggest that older, white males with high seniority but relatively less education were the most severely affected, while Remy and Sawers (1984) claim that the most severe effects were felt by women and minorities. Wallace anxi Rothschild (1988) gxnju: out that findings tend to differ depending on whether the secondary and tertiary effects of closings are considered. Men are 116 perhaps more likely to suffer from the immediate effects of factory closings (since men comprise a larger percentage of the workforce in most manufacturing industries), but in the long-term, when ripple effects spread to service and retail establishments, women end up bearing the larger burden. Nearly all the research following the fairly early study of Gordus, Jarley, and Ferman concludes that non—whites have suffered disproportionately to whites. The impact of plant closings on the industrial relations system is two—fold. First, many of the closings during the 1970s and 1980s occurred in the highly unionized sectors of heavy manufacturing.1 Therefore, many union jobs and entire bargaining units were lost (Cornfield, 1987), a fact embedded in the arguments of Leo Troy (1990) and the other structural change theorists. And even tjmnmfli there remains ea debate over time relative magnitude (ME structural effects, rm) one argues that plant closings had no impact on the system at all. Farber (1987) and. Freeman. and. Medoff (1984), while critical of the structural change explanation in general, do 1 However, the image of plant closings as mainly limited to old factories in the rust belt is far from correct. While it is true that communities such as Youngstown, Akron, Flint, and Gary, which were centers of old—line heavy industry, were devastated, the bulk of closings, particularly during early— 1980s, were among relatively small and relatively new businesses-—which, historically, have had high failure rates- -many of which were located in the interior South (Wallace and Rothschild, 1988). 117 conclude that somewhere between 10 and 20 percent of the decline in unionization is accounted for by deindustrialization. In addition, bargaining outcomes may have been affected by the increase in plant closings. Some argue that the image of closed plants created enough fear to force unions into agreeing to historically large and perhaps misguided concessions (Perrucci, Perrucci, Targ, and Targ, 1988; Slaughter 1983). Kovach and Millspaugh (1987, p. 48) point out that, The [UAW] agreed tt>Immm3 than one billion dollars in givebacks, in return for both effects and decision bargaining rights in future plant closings... The United Food and Commercial Workers Union agreed to production line speed—up and cost—of—living freezes at Armour Meats in return for management assurances of security against unannounced future shutdown. Likewise, the tire industry’s most recent pact with the United Rubber Workers Union contains a management guarantee against plant closings in return for wage concessions representing a 13 percent decrease in labor costs over the life of the contract. Although detractors submit that union concessions of the early-19803 were actually small considering the state of labor markets at the time (Hamermesh, 1989), the rhetoric of concession—bargaining may have made organized workers uneasy about their union status. It was not uncommon for employers to use non—union facilities as the basis for comparison in 118 concession bargaining (see the .Milwaukee Spring' decision above), and gflmflxxs of closed Luflflfll'plants were frequently used. against unions during organizing campaigns (Gagala, 1983). In short, there is much evidence that the atmosphere created by the sharp rise in closings was turned to the advantage of employers-—both during organizing campaigns and in negotiations. But whether employers, to any great degree, actually closed—down operations to escape unionization is a more complex issue. Some plant closings were the result of firmi failures, while others were linked tXD single establishment closings or the (often related) relocation of work (Bluestone and Harrison, 1983). While it would seem implausible that ea business owner vmnflxi go out-of-business deliberately to escape a bargaining relationship, 1978 amendments to the Bankruptcy Code may have made that option more attractive. Debtors are now allowed to retain a certain amount of money to be used for future investments or as retirement income; they need not pay out everything to creditors (Bluestone and Harrison, 1983; Barlett and Steele, 1992). Dismantling a unionized business and re-emerging with enough cash—in—hand to start a nonunion business at a "greenfield" site is, tummy: law, quite possible. In the 1970s there ‘were approximately 25,000 bankruptcies filed annually, in the 1980s the number climbed to an average of 119 63,500 per year (Bartlett and Steele, 1992, p. 68). Likewise, the number of firms that never emerged from Chapter 11 rose similarly. The concurrent increase in the number of professional bankruptcy consultants rmn/ have made ii; even more likely that some percentage of those failures were undertaken for strategic, not emergency, reasons (Barlett and Steel, 1992). Bankruptcy reorganization, if not complete firm failure, has certainly been used as a reason to void union contracts, particularly after the practice was approved by the Supreme Court in the case of NLRB v. Bildisco and Bildisco (465 US 513 (1984))(George, 1985a; Kurtz, walton énmi Wells, 1990; Wren and Murmann, 1990). In that case, the Court considered whether collective bargaining agreements were normal executory contracts under Section 365(a) of Chapter 11. If they were, then they could be rejected by debtors—in— possession. ‘ Lower courts had a problem applying Section 365(a) rationale to labor agreements, because such agreements have their own standing under federal law (Labor—Management Relations Act of 1947, Section 301 (29 USC 141—197)). Some courts had held that employers had no more right to void collective bargaining agreements tlmni to suspend time Fair Labor Standards Act (Keating, 1994). Certainly paying less than minimum wage would help a firm "get back on its feet," but it is clearly not legal. The Supreme Court determined, 120 however, that employers in Chapter 11 should be allowed to reject labor agreements without being required to bargain to impasse. At about the same time, Congress was debating an amendment to the Bankruptcy Code following the unfavorable constitutional review of a provision of the 1978 act. Organized labor was able to have included in the new legislation Section 1113, the so—called Packwood Amendments, which require a nine—step test before an agreement can be rejected. McClain (1992, p. 191) writes, however: But Section JJJLL envisioned as ea pro— labor response to Bildisco has failed to provide armor for collective bargaining agreements eumi has actually placed laborers in a worse position than before its enactment...[N]earhy every decision since 1984 has granted the debtor's petition for rejection of the collective bargaining agreement. Rejection of an agreement in itself does not end a union-management relationship; the employer is still required to bargain to impasse over new terms of employment. How much of an obligation remains after rejection is a bit unclear. George (1985a) notes that if the Supreme: Court had. not intended to give debtors more leeway in their bargaining obligations, then it put them in the illogical position of having been better off before rejection, when they could make unilateral changes, than after. An additional point is that the local relationship may 121 be more fragile when no contract is in force. Union security clauses are rm) longer binding sum} the so—called "contract bar," which prevents the filing of a decertification petition during most of the life of an agreement is also lifted. Without such protections, and during a time of near certain uneasiness among employees, a union may find itself under severe pressure-—particularly if an employer views the union an as obstacle to reorganization (Pendergast, 1993). Lawler (1990, p. 179) writes: Although not terminating union representation, time trustee cu? debtor— in—possession could act unilaterally to change personnel policies without first negotiating such changes with the union. Besides undermining the union's bargaining position, organized labor saw this as a means cf Lfltimately ushering out the union. In this research, I use Dun and Bradstreet data as reported in the Firm Failure Record.2 The measure is of firm failures kn/jyear and industry, per 10,000 firms. .A firm failure :us defined as ea finn going cnmeof—business owing money. Businesses which closed for other reasons, such as retirement or illness, are not included in the figure. ’ Descriptive statistics are found in the next chapter. 122 2. Plant relocations. The link between firm failure or bankruptcy reorganization and deunionization is a bit speculative. However, there is Immfii mare evidence that ‘relocations—- sometimes of entire firms, sometimes of establishments, and sometimes of jobs——have been undertaken to escape unionization (Gordon, 1977; Jaffee, 1986, 1988). Throughout the 20th century there has been a southward movement of industry, and more recently a movement "offshore" no other countries (Bluestone anmi Bluestone, 1982). The textile industry, which was located primarily in the Northeast 111 the lfhfli century, is rmwv largely ea southern industry; the center of the U.S. tire industry has moved from Ohio to Oklahoma; and apparel manufacturers, who once employed thousands of mmmkers in rmmtheastern cities have shifted enormous amounts of production overseas. The movement of rmnur other industries t1) southern aumi western "sunbelt" regions. accelerated (during (flue 1970s and 119805 (Bluestone and Bluestone, 1992; Storper and Walker, 1984). There are many reasons why firms relocate, particularly Us the South» Cheaper energy costs, especialhy in areas served by the Tennessee Valley Authority, laxer environmental regulations, and tax inducements are among the more frequently mentioned factors (Wallace and Rothschild, 1988). But labor costs and (the related) union presence are factors 123 as well. Bluestone and Harrison (1982, p. 165) write: "During the 1950s and 1960s, the practice of running from unions greW'sM) much that inf the 1970s (flue northern—based industrial unions had been severely weakened." They cite a Wall Street Journal article, in which a plant location consultant stated, "Labor costs are the big thing far and away. Nine out of ten times you can hang it on labor costs and unionization." And an economic development representative from Greenville, Mississippi admitted that his community actively discourages the location there of firms that are likely txa be unionized, so as run: to damage the reputation of the area as a union—free haven. Caldwell (1981), in an article concerning the legality of communities’ activities in defense of their non—union status, writes (p. 679): [T]he fortuitously dropped union authorization card in a plant restroom, or a report that a guest at a local motel used 51 credit card issued t1) a labor union, will send ripples of alarm throughout the community. Elaborate ’Christmas tree’ communication networks will spring into action like a community DEW line, passing the dread word rapidly from merchant to manager, from minister to mayor, that 'the union is in town.’ Most communities will greet this announcement with the enthusiasm of Atlantans awaiting General Sherman. Caldwell cites many instances :hi which individuals—- clergy, newspaper editors, and (ordinary townspeople--even 124 those with no formal connection to the targeted employer, organized against unionization in their community. So long as they are not acting as "agents" of the employer, such allies are largely beyond the scope of the Act. It is easy to find many anecdotes similar to the ones just mentioned. But, as well, in a quantitative study, David Jaffee (1986, 1988) found that the strongest negative predictor of where a firm relocated within the continental United States between 1970 and 1980 was a state’s rate of unionization. He concludes emphatically (p. 313): The results from this analysis provide no support for the conventional industrial location perspective...TTm2most important factor overall was the general level of labor organization within a state. Further evidence is provided by Verma and Kochan (1985), who studied the creation of a nonunion sector within a firm. Zhi 1957 the observed firm vans 80 percent unionized. But during the next 25 years, the company developed a strategy of vigorous opposition to unions at new locations, and favored those locations with the placement of work. The union sector continued to shrink and by 1982, less than half of the firm’s employees were union members—~a reduction of nearly 50 percent in 25 years. One exception to this trend occurred in the auto assembly industry where a "southern strategy" of operating non—union was abandoned in the face of union resistance in 125 the 1970s. As auto manufacturers agreed to neutrality and even bargaining unit accretion at southern plants all establishments became unionized (Katz and MacDuffie, 1994). In sum, the weight of both the quantitative and qualitative evidence suggests that unionization may be one factor in relocation decisions. Unfortunately, there are no systematically collected data that track actual relocations. As 51 proxy, scholars typically 'have looked an: shifts in employment or establishments from region—to-region. I will continue that practice here and use as a proxy for relocation the cumulative percent point change in the distribution of establishments across states, by industry, for each period under study. Statistics were derived from the Census Bureau’s annual series County Business Patterns. This is essentially the procedure used by Jaffee (1986, 1988). Based on the previous research, I believe that there exists some link between relocation and the desire to escape unionization. 3. subcontracting. Muoh less clear':u3 the extent (x) which unionization plays a role in input substitution. Based on the volume of Board and court cases involving subcontracting, and the widespread presence of subcontracting language in contracts, it appears that union officials are quite concerned with the practice of substituting nonunion labor for union labor. 126 There is also some scholarly conjecture that subcontracting has been used to escape unionization (Bluestone and Harrison, 1982; Holmes, 1986; Pfeffer emmi Baron, 1988), Inn: little research evidence to support this speculation. While the Europeans (Holmes, 1986) and Japanese (Watanabe, 1971) have studied the issue quite thoroughly, empirical vmndc in the IldS. is underdeveloped. Currently, there is ea growing literature 1J1 response rm) "contingent worker“ issues, but rmxfl: evidence (xxmas frle individual industry and even firm—level case studies (Dunlop Commission Report, 1995). Both definitional and, moreover, data problems are stalling this research. Bureau of Labor Statistics information shows a huge increase in employment in the personnel services industry during the past decade, which suggests that many employers increased their use of contract workers and leased employees. Lhfikmtunately, there is rm) precise information on where these workers were being employed.3 Neither is there an accepted definition of subcontracting (Holmes, 1986). The hiring of contractors to 3 Leased employees were counted on the payroll of the leasing company. If a manufacturing firm leased all of its production workers, it would have been counted as having zero workers in that category. Needless to say, with the growth in leasing arrangements the usefulness of establishment-level employment information is questionable (Personal inquiry to the Rhode Island Department of Employment Training’s Labor Market Information Unit, August 9, 1995.) 127 provide clerical, accounting, and maintenance services, the leasing of production workers, and the outsourcing of work to job shops have all been termed "subcontracting." Although the increase in leased production workers will likely have an impact on future research, most of the work done to date on manufacturing has focused on outsourcing (Kelley and Harrison, 1990). In either case, subcontracting is a difficult phenomenon to measure. There is neither systematically collected data, nor truly adequate proxies. The hatter studies have used original surveys, which have included direct questions to employers about their outsourcing' behavior. 2\ possible though admittedly risky proxy is the relative change in the number (ME small establishments within EH1 industry (Imrie, 1986; Piore and Sabel, 1984). Since large firms typically outsource to smaller firms that specialize in the production of components, an increase in outsourcing may be reflected in a change in the relative number of small establishments within an industry. Piore and Sabel (1984) note this relationship between "craft" and "mass" producers in their book the Second Industrial Divide. One of the more thorough and recent treatments. of subcontracting in the United States is the work of Kelley and Harrison (1990). Several years ago they conducted a survey of over 1000 production managers in metalworking and asked 128 them about the extent of subcontracting by their firms and their motivations for subcontracting. Kelley and Harrison made specific inquiries about industrial relations practices. They found (p. 1283): The results for the labor relations variables enie somewhat surprising. By itself, independent of the cost of labor, we find no statistically significant evidence that subcontracting practices of U.S. manufacturers are part of a union avoidance strategy. As for joint labor— management problem solving, we find that such collaboration is only associated with ea significant commitment ti) avoid subcontracting when there is also a union. In non-union plants, such collaborative arrangements actually lead to an increased likelihood of subcontracting. Of course there~ are shortcomings to time Kelley' and Harrison study: it covers only one industry and relies on the responses of production managers, who may or may not have been completely candid about their motivations. Nevertheless, it is the best American research available on the issue that I have uncovered, and indicates that the conjecture concerning the connection between subcontracting and union avoidance may be somewhat misguided. I use as a measure of outsourcing, the annual rate of change in the percentage of establishments employing fewer than 100 workers, by industry. This figure is derived from County Business Patterns. While I believe that there may be a link between outsourcing and a desire to escape 129 unionization, the weight of the research evidence tempers my expectations. 4. Technological change. I am also skeptical of the link between technological change eumi union avoidance. Haddad (1984, I3. 150) writes that, "One of most serious problems that unions face around the issue of high technology is membership erosion." Indeed in a number of cases that has proven true. ,mMi for that reason, ii: has become axiomatic that unions resist technological change (Hieb and Moody, 1981). However, again, the evidence is not very supportive (Bamber, 1986; Cyert and Mowry, 1987; Keefe and Kphl, 1993). In fact, Weikle and Wheeler (1984) report that their survey" of local unions leaders revealed "a rather mild form of encouragement" of new technology. Keefe and Kohl (1993) submit that unionists in manufacturing believe that the competitiveness of their firms is linked tx> technological development. Several (M3 the larger industrial unions (the Steelworkers and Mineworkers, for example) have actively promoted technology, and even, at times, have been critical of employers for failing to make capital improvements. It would seem that many union leaders accept time argument timn: improvements iii compensation and quality' of worklife are tied to technological advances. Helen Rainbird (1988, p. 174) writes: 130 Trade unions recognize that companies invest in new technology to remain competitive. Their policy is therefore not to resist technological change, but to attempt to control its introduction in seeking agreements on new technology, disclosure of information and job security...Unions recognize timm; there are positive and negative effects of new technology on jobs, and invariably stress the need to seek the positive benefits in negotiations. The issue becomes more contentious when entire bargaining units or even entire crafts are threatened. For example, in 1962 the International Typographical Union carried out a 114 day strike against New York City newspapers to prevent the introduction of "cold type" processes. The union won a short-term victory, but eventually dropped its opposition to the new technology in 1974. By the mid~1980s, the ITU, the nation’s oldest union, was out—of—business, forced to merge with the Communication Workers due to shrinking' membership (Keefe and Kohl, 1993). A. similar battle was fought on the railroads when diesel engines eliminated. the need for firemen (Troy, 1990). And the introduction. of ;prefabricated.:materials has created. some problems in construction, although Allen (1986) reports that, even there, the resistance to new technology has been exaggerated. Since most manufacturing establishments are rm) longer organized along craft lines, the likelihood that 131 technological change would wipe out an entire bargaining unit has probably lmmai diminished. rThe weight CHE the evidence does suggest that there can be negative employment impacts of new technology, but these vary considerably across occupations (Cyert and Mowery, 1987). Because manufacturing bargaining units often include a number of occupations, job loss would have to be extreme before the bargaining relationship itself is threatened. The study of technological effects suffers from some of the same shortcomings as the study of subcontracting. Cyert and Mowery complain (1987, p. 29): If we could measure the rates of invention, innovation, and diffusion in the U.S. economy, we could simplify greatly the analysis of technology’s impact on employment. Such measurements, however, are far from simple, the United States and most other industrial nations do rmm: collect systematic time series data on the rates of diffusion of specific new technologies. Without such data, proxies abound. Total factor productivity, new capital investment, capital vintage, computer—intensity, emmi the employment share cu? scientists and engineers have all been used (Howell and Wolff, 1992). In this study, I use the average annual rate of change in new capital investment, 1J1 constant dollars, in! industry, .as reported 111 the Annual Ehnnma/ of Manufactures. I presume that there may be a link between technological change and a 132 desire to escape unionization. But, once again, based on the research evidence, the link is likely not a strong one. C. Loss of certification. Here there is really no question of motivation. Nearly the only reason why an employer or unit members would challenge the right of a union to represent workers is out of a desire to escape the obligations of unionization and collective bargaining,‘ whether such obligations include the payment of dues or agency fees on the part of employees, or the necessity of bargaining on the part of employers. Without a good idea of the number of bargaining relationships in the economy, it is very difficult to interpret time trend 1J1 decertification activity. The raw figures indicate: a that RD (employee—iniaited) elections surged. in mid-1970s, when the annual average went from approximately 400 per year for the decade before 1975 to over 800 per year for the decade following. The highest year was 1980 with 902 elections. By the end of the 1980s, however, the figure had gone back down to around 600 per year. The number of RM (employer-iniated) elections has decreased from about 400 per year in the early 1970s to only about 200 per ‘ One might argue that employers act out of a concern with violating the law by dealing with a non-majoritarian representative. But, considering the passive enforcement of the Act, I cannot imagine that that concern is an overwhelming one. 133 year in the 19803. In 1990, there were only 87 RM elections (NLRB, Annual Reports, various years). Even though these trends may seem favorable to unions today, it; is important ti) note that time union "win" rate seems to have been declining as well. When the RD election trend increased in time 1970s, unions were successful in maintaining representation in approximately thirty percent of elections; by the end of the 1980s, that figure had slipped to just over twenty percent. The statistics for RM elections are even more dramatic. In the early—1970s, when the number of electhmms was high, unions were consistently retaining representation about forty percent of the time; now that figure is also closer to twenty percent. Perhaps a larger problem with the decertification data is that we have no way of accurately figuring how many elections per bargaining unit are occurring. My research shows, énmi other research implies, that there 1mm; been a fairly sharp decline in the number of bargaining relationships in the economy. Based on the sample used here, the decline :hi the number (if pre—existing relationships between 1980 and 1990 was 24.4 percent across fourteen manufacturing industries.5 Since we also know that the rate 5 This figure is simply the percentage difference between the number of relationships contained in the panel in 1980 and in 1990. That is: ((1032—1365)/1365)*100=—24.4. 134 of new organizing in manufacturing was quite low during the decade, we are fairly safe in assuming that there are fewer bargaining relationships today than there were fifteen or twenty years ago. Therefore, even though the average annual number of decertification elections has declined, the rate of elections ,per LmUJ; very' likely’ has increased. Further, because of the declining union success rate, the magnitude of the impact (fl? decertification elections (ii the industrial relations system may be continuing to rise (Levine, 1989). The measure used here is the number of decertification elections per 10,000 units, by industry. The numerator comes from. NLRB Annual Reports, and is simply the number of decertification elections per industry, per year. The denominatcm‘ was figured kn! first calculating total union membership per industry, and then dividing that figure by the average size of a bargaining unit in the sample of cases used in this study, resulting in an approximation of the number of units per industry. The number of decertification elections per bargaining unit were figured, and the result was multiplied by 10,000 to mirror the way the firm failure data are reported. D. summary. The preceding discussion was intended to aid hypotheses generation. The first conclusion is that firm failures were more likely to have been associated with economic distress 135 than union avoidance, though it is possible--due to amendments to the law——that some failures were strategically undertaken with the goal of escaping collective bargaining. Second, there is likely to have been a mmch stronger link between plant relocation and a desire to escape bargaining obligations. There is quite a bit of both qualitative and quantitative evidence to suggest that employers moved operations away from union sites to non—union sites in other states or other nations. Third, the connection between both types of input substitution——labor for labor and technology for labor——and union avoidance appears rather weak. Fourth, there appears to have been a rising trend in decertification activity, particularly vmmNi the decrease ill the number of bargaining units is considered. These conclusions lead to the following research hypotheses. D. Hypotheses. H1. The disappearance rate of local collective bargaining relationships across manufacturing industries is significantly and positively related to the number of firm failures per 10,000 firms. For the entire pooled sample, it is expected that the disappearance rate of local collective bargaining relationships will be higher in industries that experienced more firm failures. Support for this hypothesis would indicate that time disappearance of reiationships is, mmat likely, associated with the economic distress of industries. 136 The hypothesis will be tested by an examination of means, simple correlations, and partial slope coefficients in multiple regression analysis. H2. The disappearance rate of local collective bargaining relationships across manufacturing industries is significantly and positively related to the percentage point change in the distribution of establishments across states by industry, controlling' for' new establishment growth and capital intensity. For the entire pooled sample, it is expected that the disappearance rate of local collective bargaining relationships will be higher in industries that have displayed 61 greater degree (if change 1J1 interstate distribution. Support for this hypothesis would be consistent with an argument that the disappearance of local relationships is associated with firm relocations to escape unionization. However, the cross—state distribution of firms may change if an industry grows more rapidly in one region than in another. Therefore, the rate of change in establishment growth by industry is controlled so that interstate shifts do not simply mask industry expansion. Further, relocation may be a function of the ability of a firm to move—~which, in turn, may be a function of the amount resources invested in plant and equipment. Therefore, capital intensity is controlled. This hypothesis Vail. be tested hw'eMi examination cm 137 means, simple correlations, and partial slope coefficients in multiple regression analysis. H3. The disappearance rate of local collective bargaining relationships across manufacturing industries is significantly enmi positively related. to time rate which this phenomenon explains the variance in relationship disappearance across industries during time pernmd will be tested. A significant result would be consistent with the proposition that looser standards of employer election conduct and tighter standards of union discipline and union security encouraged more union decertification activity. The first time period variable is associated with disappearances logged after 1980; the second with those logged after 1983, and the third with those recorded after 1986. 146 In the next chapter, the data and methods used to test the preceding hypotheses are discussed. Chapter VI. Data and Methods. A. Introduction In this chapter I describe the data and methods used to test the hypotheses presented at the end of the Chapter V. First, I discuss the sample and sampling technique used to calculate the dependent variable. I then discuss the methods for analysis of the data, and problems likely to be encountered. I conclude with a description of formulae and descriptive statistics relating to the dependent and independent variables. B. The sample. There is virtually no data measuring the characteristics of local collective bargaining relationships. 1x:is, in fact, impossible tmetanswer precisely how mmmu/ such relationships exist. Neither the economic censuses nor the Bureau of Labor Statistics’ establishment survey contain information on local bargaining relationships. Hence, most of what we know about union growth and decline comes by way of the Census Bureau’s Current Population Survey; which” as 61 household. survey, provides informatitml about individuals not firms 3(Xsft:—l)+b4(xnct-1)‘i—bS(xdct-1)+bG(xestt—1) + b7(Xempt-1) +b8(xcapt—1)+b9(xpent-1)+b10(xtd) [3] Where the additional variable is: 1(a): categorical variable representing periods after 1980, 1983, and 1986. It should be noted that Models 2, 3, 4 are each run once to test changes associated with disappearances recorded after 1980, 1983 and 1986. Results of the three runs will be placed in the same table so that they may be compared across time periods. 3. models 5 through 7. In Models 5 through 7, cross—products of the time period dummies éumi variables (if primary theoretical interest are included in the model. The purpose of this model is to test hypotheses H11 through H15. While the dummy variable tests for changes in the intercept across time periods, the cross— 168 products test for significant changem; in. slope ‘variables across time periods. 'Was there 61 significant change away from firm failure and towards the other variables as the periods passed? Therefore: Y: a+b1(xfft-1)+b2(xdist-1)+b3(xsft-1)+b4(xnct-1)+b5(xdct-1)+ b6(xtd)+b7(xfft-1) *(Xtd)+b8(xdist-1) 1k(Xtd)+b9(xsft-l)1'r (Xtd)+b10(xnct—1)* (Xtd)+b11(xdctt-1)*(Xtd)+b11(xestt-1)+ b12(X +b13(X +b14(xpent-l) [4] erupt-1) capt-l) Where the additional variables are: (x,,.,,)*(x,,)= firm failure rate, by industry, for T-l times period effect. (1.1..-,)*(Xu)= the percent point change in the distribution of establishments across states, by industry, for T-l times period effect. (x,,,,,)*(xm)= average annual rate of change in the relative percentage of establishments with fewer than 100 employees, by industry, for T-l times current period effect. (lub,)*(xm)= average annual rate of change in investment in new capital, by industry, for T-l times period effect. (L¢,_,)*(Xtd)= decertification rate, by industry, for T-l times period effect. H. Descriptive statistics. Before turning ti) the research. results in time next chapter, I examine the attributes and patterns of the variables through descriptive statistics. First I present cross—industry comparisons on single variables, then cross— variable comparisons for single industries. 169 1. variables. a. Disappearance rate. Table 6.2. Disappearance rate, by industry, 3-year periods, 1977-1990. SIC/Industry Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 4 Mean (S.D.) 20 Food .0448 .1641 .0583 .0647 .0830 (.0547) 22 Textiles .0698 .0750 .1719 .1490 .1164 (.0517) 24 Lumber .0238 .0976 .1903 .0455 .0893 (.0741) 25 Furniture .0323 .0000 .0684 .0000 .0252 (.0326) 26 Paper .0268 .0414 .0303 .0538 .0381 (.0122) 28 Chemicals .0072 .0365 .0562 .0898 .0474 (.0347) 29 Petroleum .0000 .0000 .0964 .0660 .0406 (.0485) 30 Rubber .0682 .0500 .0544 .1100 .0706 (.0274) 32 Stone, Glass, C1ay.0353 .0488 .0939 .1301 .0770 (.0434) 33 Primary Metals .0125 .0506 .0565 .1348 .0636 (.0513) 34 Fabricated Metals .0202 .0417 .0807 .0932 .0590 (.0338) 35 Machinery .0370 .0604 .0868 .1058 .0725 (.0301) 36 Electrical Equip. .0379 .0551 .0526 .0579 .0509 (.0089) 37 Transport. Equip. .0328 .0847 .1060 .0953 .0797 (.0325) Mean .0321 .0576 .0859 .0854 (S.D.) (.0321) (.0409) (.0455) (.0403) Note: Calculated from the key files of the Department of Labor's private sector collective bargaining agreements archive and the Register of Reporting Labor Organizations, 1980, 1983, 1986, 1990. In Table 6.2, several characteristics of relationship disappearance can be observed. It should be noted that the disappearance of relationships and the disappearance of firms is not the same thing. Firm failures, which will be considered below, Hey kxa one cause of reflationship disappearance, Inn; a relationship rmn/ cease for tine other reasons implied by Equathmi l as well. First, we can see that the weighted mean disappearance rate jumped 100 percent from 1980 to 1983, another 50 percent between 1983 and 1986, but remain about the same to the end of the decade. What is interesting, however, is that the standard deviation of the disappearance rate narrowed slightly during the final period. l70 This would suggest that the phenomenon of relationship disappearance became more generalized and less confined to a few strongly impacted industries. Indeed, we see that in Period 3, the jump in the overall mean can be accounted for, almost. exclusively, in! increases :hi tlme means cfif several industries of 9 enui lO percentage points (i.e. Lumber, Textiles, and Petroleum). In the final period there are no such rapid increases. However, nearly half of the industries under study (6 of 14) show disappearance rates of at least 10 percent. This narrowing of standard deviation is consistent with the argument that disappearances became more diffuse later 111 the decade. It will lxe important t1) see whether there was a concurrent diffusion of economic distress. Examining the disappearance trend across industries reveals that most display rising trends throughout the period, Inn: several industries sflxnvzmore complex patterns. Lumber, for example, rises sharply from Period 1.tx> 2 and flmmn Period 2 t1) 3, but falls rather dramatically between Periods 3 and 4. This pattern may reflect first the slowdown in construction caused by high interest rates in the late— 1970s and the economic recession of the early 19808, and then the building boom of the mid—to-late 19805. Similarly, the trend in Petroleum seems to reflect the fortunes of that industry as well. As oil prices fell during the mid—1980s, the industry, for the first time, begins registering 171 disappearances. The Imma: puzzling tnmaxi occurs If] Food Products. Periods 1, 3, and 4 all show disappearance rates of approximately 5 or 6 percent, but Period 2 climbs to 16 percent. When statistics for all variables are considered by industry, the reason for this unusual pattern may become more apparent. b. Firm failure rate. Observing the trend in lagged firm failures (Table 6.3), we do see some evidence that supports the argument that economic distress did, indeed, become greater and more generalized as the decade progressed. The change from Period L1 to Period 2_1 does not correspond to the increase in disappearance rate seen above, but the later trend becomes much more consistent. The large jump in firm failure rate of 140 percent from Period 21 to Period 34, and the somewhat smaller jump from Period 3_1 to Period 4_,, track fairly closely the trend in disappearances. So too does the narrowing of the standard deviation in firm failures. The more widespread incidence of firm failures between 1983 and 1986 (Period 44) may explain the more widespread incidence of relationship disappearances recorded between 1986 and 1990, Period 4. 172 Table 6.3. Firm failure rate, per 10,000 firms, by industry, 3-year periods, 1974- 1986. SIC/Industry Period 1,1 Period 2,,Period 3,, Period 4,l Mean (S.D.) 20 Food 32.33 29.00 70.00 122.33 63.42 (43.46) 22 Textiles 71.33 65.33 104.33 118.67 89.92 (25.72) 24 Lumber 33.00 29.33 94.67 133.00 72.50 (50.25) 25 Furniture 82.67 77.33 184.67 156.00 125 17 (53.50) 26 Paper 25.67 28.33 58.33 90.33 50.67 (30.31) 28 Chemicals 33.67 32.00 68.33 113.67 61.92 (38.35) 29 Petroleum NA NA NA 187.00 187.00 (00.00) 30 Rubber 40.00 41.00 82.00 119.33 70.58 (37.94) 32 Stone,Glass,C1ay 26.00 25.00 70.33 96.67 54.50 (35.17) 33 Primary Metals 33.00 34.33 120.67 165.67 88.42 (65.84) 34 Fabricated Metals 32.00 24.67 76.33 132.00 66.25 (49.42) 35 Machinery 31.67 27.33 98.00 111.33 67.08 (43.77) 36 Electrical Equip. 73.00 45.67 102.00 148.67 92.33 (44.04) 37 Transport Equip. 78.33 69.00 138.67 179.67 116.42 (52.26) Mean 45.59 40.64 97.56 133.88 (S.D.) (21.77) (18.24) (34.73) (29.63) Source: Dun and Bradstreet, Firm Failure Record 1974-1986. c. Change in cross-state distribution. In Table 6.4 we can observe the proxy variable for plant relocation. The variable represents the overall percentage point change in the distribution of establishments, by industry, across states per three year period. We can seen that over the period of 1974 tx> 1986, average change was remarkably constant, and actually decreased 51 bit between Period L1 and Period 44. Across industries, however, there was some variation and even a few counter trends. Transportation Equipment, for example, showed a fairly strong increase :hi Period. 44- II: is interesting tub speculate whether this represents a policy effect since both major :relocation. decisions discussed. earlier—-Otis Elevator" and 173 Milwaukee Spring——involved this industry and its major union, the United Auto Workers. Interesting as well is the spike in Period 21 for the Food Products industry, which may help explain the Period 2 increase in the recorded disappearance rate observed earlier. Table 6.4. Percentage point change in distribution of establishments across states, by industry, 3-year periods, 1974-1986. SIC/Industry Period idPeriod 24Period 34Period 4.1 Mean(s.D.) 20 Food 3.00 5.35 4.06 3.18 3.90(1.07) 22 Textiles 7.29 4.38 6.26 3.61 5.39(1.69) 24 Lumber 3.99 4.83 3.80 3.90 4.13(0.47) 25 Furniture 7.72 6.26 5.55 6.92 6.61(0.92) 26 Paper 6.93 5.72 4.09 5.67 5.60(1.16) 28 Chemicals 3.83 4.83 5.28 4.00 4.48(0.69) 29 Petroleum 5.67 8.56 7.69 6.57 7.12(1.27) 30 Rubber 6.30 5.99 4.63 6.17 5.77(0.77) 32 Stone, Glass, Clay 7.13 3.84 4.74 4.83 5.14(1.40) 33 Primary Metals 4.94 4.82 5.32 5.60 5.06(0.50) 34 Fabricated Metals 5.61 3.83 4.88 3.43 4.44(0.99) 3S Machinery 5.48 4.79 4.78 3.47 4.63(0.84) 36 Electrical Equip. 7.84 7.41 7.89 5.13 7.07(1.31) 37 Transport. Equip. 5.10 5.29 5.05 8.41 5.96(1.63) Mean 5.74 5.42 5.28 5.06 (S.D.) (1.54) (1.32) (1.24) (1.57) Source: Bureau of the Census, County Business Patterns, 1974, 1977, 1980, 1983, 1986. d. Rate of growth in new capital expenditures. Table 6.5 reveals that, in general, new capital expenditures folloW'lgeneral economic trends. During' the recession of the early 19805, only Petroleum showed an average annual increase. But as the oil glut of the mid— 19808 depressed petroleum prices, capital expenditures began to fall in that industry as well. Below, we will compare new capital expenditures to employment trends to see if capital expenditures may have been labor displacing. It will be particularly interesting to see how the two variables compare in Rubber, all of which showed fairly large increases expenditures in Period 44. Fabricated Metals, 174 and Transportation Equipment in new capital Table 6.5. Average annual rate of change in new capital expenditures, by industry, 3-year periods, 1974-1986. SIC/Industry Period ldPeriod 24Period 34Period 4.1 Mean (S.D.) 20 Food 4.33 1.26 -6.25 3.02 .59 (4.73) 22 Textiles 2.43 -3.01 -4.20 -1.45 -1.56 (2.89) 24 Lumber -1.55 -0.57 -21.02 9.15 —3.50 (12.64) 25 Furniture -0.25 4.33 -4.87 5.84 1.26 (4.84) 26 Paper 6.19 5.02 -6.86 3.79 -2.04 (6.01) 28 Chemicals 9.15 -7.26 -12.36 0.58 -2.47 (9.40) 29 Petroleum 1.03 6.89 5.27 -19.83 -1.66 (12.36) 30 Rubber -0.94 -0.27 -10.80 18.73 1.68 (12.35) 32 Stone,Glass,C1ay -0.87 7.33 ~22.13 8.60 -1.77 (14.21) 33 Primary Metals —1.22 -2.84 -12.41 -11.11 -6.90 (5.68) 34 Fabricated Metals 2.58 3.93 -1S.18 14.33 1.42 (12.24) 35 Machinery 2.92 10.18 -11.62 -0.36 0.28 (9.08) 36 Electrical Equip. NA NA NA NA NA 37 Transport. Equip. 10.50 8.40 -15.67 27.95 7.79 (17.93) Mean 2.64 2.56 -10.62 4.56 S.D. (3.96) (5.17) (7.38) (12.25) Source: Bureau of the Census, Annual Survey of Manufactures, 1974—1986 e. Annual rate of change in small establishments. The trend in small establishments may tell us something about outsourcing behavior in industries. Every industry has shown some overall increase in the relative number of smaller establishments, with Primary Metals showing the largest overall increase. Again, it anJ_ibe necessary t1) compare employment patterns with the trend in small establishments before any stronger conclusion. can. be gains in employment. These observations may reflect changes that were occurring in the tire industry, a former union stronghold, which was particularly hard hit by plant closings and relocations. 190 Table 6.19. SIC 30. Rubber. Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 4 Disappearance Rate .0682 .0500 .0544 .1100 Firm Failures/10,000 firms 40.00 41.00 82.00 119.33 Cross-State Distribution (% change) 6.30 5.99 4.63 6.17 Decertifications/10,000 units 82.27 135.38 108.01 119.72 Small Firm Growth (ann. % change) 0.76 -0.34 1.20 —0.65 New Capital Expenditures (ann. % change)-0.94 -0.27 —10.80 18.73 Establishment Growth (ann. % change) 4.11 3.52 3.35 2.46 Union Penetration (% workers) 38.73 32.67 29.10 23.97 Capital Intensity (% assets) 33.33 33.67 35.67 37.00 Employment Growth (ann. % change) 1.54 0.28 -0.44 3.83 Source: see Table 6.12. i. SIC 32, Stone, Glass, and Clay. Like the rubber industry, Stone, Glass, and Clay shows a increase in disappearance rate in the final period, although the trend is steadier throughout the decade (Table 6.20). Both firm failures and decertifications rise at about the same rate as disappearances. In Period 2, there is evidence that capital investments came at the expense of labor, and in Period 4 cross—state changes are not justified by an increase in the number of establishments, a trend consistent with 191 hypotheses. Table 6.20. SIC 32. Stone, Glass and Clay. Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 4 Disappearance Rate .0353 .0488 .0939 .1301 Firm Failures/10,000 firms 26.00 25.00 70.33 96.67 Cross-State Distribution (% change) 7.13 3.84 4.74 4.83 Decertifications/10,000 units 27.08 46.99 73.96 111.05 Small Firm Growth (ann. % change) 0.50 -.47 .72 -0.17 New Capital Expenditures (ann. % change)~0.87 7.33 ~22.13 8.60 Establishment Growth (ann. % change) 1.56 -1.99 1.10 -0.33 Union Penetration (% workers) 48.33 47.97 39.97 29.87 Capital Intensity (% assets) 45.33 46.67 48.33 45.33 Employment Growth (ann. % change) -1.89 -1.12 -5.28 1.23 Source: see Table 6.12. 3'. SIC 33, Primary Metals. A rise in the firm failure rate and changes in location during Period 3 and Period 4 appear to be closely related with the extreme rise in disappearances (Table 6.21). Period 4 displays the most precipitous increase in failures and also a stark divergence between geographic location and establishment growth. Although there is also an increase in the decertification rate entering the final period, in comparison to other industries the rate is actually quite low. There has been relatively high small firm growth, coupled vnifll decreases ij1 employment. Capital bar labor substitutions are not apparent at the industry—level, since the rate of new capital expenditures decreases in every 192 period. Table 6.21. SIC 33. Primary Metals. Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 4 Disappearance Rate .0125 .0506 .0565 .1348 Firm Failures/10,000 firms 33.00 34.33 120.67 165.67 Cross-State Distribution (% change) 4.94 4.82 5.32 5.60 Decertifications/10,000 units 26.44 36.80 58.73 75.27 Small Firm Growth (ann. % change) 1.13 -1.03 3.02 -0.80 New Capital Expenditures (ann. % change) -1.22 -2.84 -12.41 -11.11 Establishment Growth (ann. % change) 0.86 -0.57 0.38 -1.64 Union Penetration (% workers) 62.07 59.67 54.87 47.67 Capital Intensity (% assets) 46.67 45.00 48.33 45.33 Employment Growth (ann. % change) —3.31 -1.39 -10.60 -2.85 Source: see Table 6.12. k. SIC 34, Fabricated.Metals. The steady increase in more lenient standards cu: employer conduct and stricter standards of union security. However, the rate had been climbing fairly steadily since the early 19708, before most of these policy reversals were made; therefore, a more careful analysis is needed before further conclusions can be drawn. None of the other variables in Equation 1 are 204 significant—-the (outsourcing gnrnqn change ii1 cross—state distribution, or new capital investment. In fact, all are signed in a direction contrary to the expectations stated in the hypotheses, with the coefficients for new capital investment and change in (cross—state distribution nearly achieving significance. 205 Ho.v.m¢ mo.v.fiss Ho.v.Qese escom.ssemm. seam.| NH.I seam. ma.l mo. seam. ssam.nesemv. seeow. eehN. mmmd KNBhd .ma secmm. eemm.l smN. eemN.I eH.I ma. mH.I sehN. «seam. eeeoh. sscmv. mama MNBhd .NH NN.I mH.| bH.| mH.I OH. mo.| smN.Issemv. Issue. eesmv. coma mmahd .HH va.l mo. mo.eeshm. ¢H.I mo. eeeww.nessmm.l eemm.n ”94¢ ZOHZD .OH mH.| sewn. om.| mo.n esmv. mo. om. MN.I ERROKO .Bmm .m om. e¢N.|eseHh. eeehv.l ma.) #0.: NN.I .BmflbZH AdBHmdo .m mo. «0. ho. mH.I ma. mH.| .BMHQ NB‘BmImmOMU .b HN.I mo. avN.u mo. pH.I MmZNBZH AGBHmdu .0 ecemm.n mo. No.1 ¢H.I mhkomO BZNSHOAQSN .m hH.I mo. mo.n ”Gadmo IMHN AddZm .v eeeNv. econ. MB‘N .BMNUNQ .m seemm. mmmDaHdfl ZMHN .N ”Edd mdmmm‘mHQ .H NH Ha OH 0 o h m m C n N H .sso«usaeuuoo unencuouou .n.b sands 206 Of the control variables, only the union penetration rate shows a significant correlation with the disappearance rate. The negative correlation indicates that, as expected, bargaining relationships in more highly organized industries were relatively more likely to have survived the decade than those in less organized industries. The trend in the dependent variable across time periods holds t1) our expectations. There aura strong correlations between the disappearance rates logged in the periods following 1980 and 1983, and a somewhat weaker though still significant correlation for the period following 1986. The weaker correlation in the latter period reflects the levelling—off of recorded disappearance rates following 1983. None of the other correlations between independent variables and the dependent variable are significant at the .10 level. There are, however, some interesting intercorrelations among independent variables. For example, the association between firm failures and decertification elections indicates that economic distress may have made it more difficult for unions txa:maintain representation rights. Bankruptcy may, indeed, have been the slippery slope to deunionization that Lawler (1990) predicted. Also noteworthy are the significant correlations between establishment growth and the relative frequency of small 207 firms, and between establishment growth and cross—state change. This pattern suggests that new establishments tended to be smaller and to have arisen in industries that displayed greater change in geographic distribution. A likely explanation is that older, larger establishments were being replaced 13! smaller establishments en: greenfiebd sites ljl other regions. The strong correlation between new capital investment and employment growth may confirnlthe earlier speculation that new technology-~at the industry level——doe8 not lead.t0iwidespread labor substitution. However, it must be remembered that the variable, as measured here, represents new spending on all forms of capital not just new technology. Table 7.3 also shows a strong association between union penetration rates and several of the independent variables. For example, unionization is negatively associated with firm failures and decertification elections. However, these associations rmn/ be spurious :U1 light tn? the correlation between unionizationenxicapital intensity. Capital intensive firms typically experience less market competitiveness and.are less affected by labor costs, which represent a relatively lower proportion of total costs. Timzpositive, though non-significant, association between establishment growth and firm failure rate should also be noted. Common sense would suggest that the two should be 208 negatively associated. However, time positive correlation indicates that establishment foundings occurred. more frequently in industries experiencing simultaneous economic difficulty. Perhaps firm failures in one region were being offset by (smaller) organization births in other regions. There aura also 51 number (if significant correlations between time periods and the independent variables. II am particularly concerned about the strong correlations between firm failure and the final two time period variables, which may make it difficult to distinguished between economic and other period effects ii1 the regression nedel. Otherwise, noteworthy patterns occur on several variables that display curvilinear trends as time passes. Firm failure rate, decertification.rate, small firnxchange, establishment growth, and the chxn) in union penetratmmn rate all correlate most strongly with the period following 1983. Employment growth and capital investment, on tine other hand, correlate nest strongly with the final period. .D. Regression models. 1. constant time model. The first regression model contains only the continuous \nariables and.predicts unit disappearances for the entire time period. 7.4. Standardized regression coefficients, lagged model, t-values in parentheses, N:56. Model 1 Establishment Growth —.4360** (-2.25) Firm Failure .3415** (2.55) Capital Intensity -.2857* (—1.73) New Capital Investment —.3284* (—1.45) Decertification Rate .0739 (0.35) Union Penetration Rate -.0323 (-0.16) Small Firm Growth .0148 (0.07) Cross-State Change .0113 (0.07) Employment Growth .0009 (0.04) R’ .36** Adj R2 .19 F value 2.12 D.W. 2.10 *** p.< .01 ** p.< .05 * p.< .10 210 The first regression model provides support only for hypothesis H1. Indeed, firm failure rates appear to be a significant predictor of local bargaining unit disappearance. The decertification rate, vflfirfl1lrmi a significant positive correlation with disappearance rate loses its significance due, I suspect, to its correlation with capital intensity. Cross-state change in the relative distribution of firms, for which there was a strong expectation of significance, is not a significant predictor of disappearance in this model. The proxy for outsourcing, small establishment growth, also shows no significance in the model, while the variable intended to approximate capital for labor substitution, new capital spending, is significant, but signed in a direction contrary to the hypothesis. Two of the control variables perform quite well in the model. Establishment growth and capital intensity are both fairly strong predictors of disappearance rate. Neither were significant as zero-order correlations, but apparently represent important attributes when partial effects are observed. Union penetration rate loses the significance it displayed as a simple correlation. Like decertification rates, I suspect that the intercorrelation of union penetration and capital intensity causes the former to be overwhelmed when partial effects are observed. In sum, the results of Model 1 (Table 7.4) indicate that 211 the ecological fallacy——trm2 evidence: indicates that employers, even. absent the» strong* economic ;pressures, as predicted by the firm failure rate, may have been more likely to take advantage of the option of "escaping" (Walton, Cutcher—Gershenfeld,énmlMcKersien 1994) collectiveebargaining relationships after 1983. Without controlling for the time juncture of 1983, the disappearance of relationships can simply be explained by its association with firm failures. The non—significant result for the post—1986 dummy variable is contrary to hypothesis H8, but is not surprising since it was seen that the change in the dependent variable levels-off after 1983. As well, the dummy variable for the post—1980 period approaches but does not reach significance. This result is also not surprising since the post—1980 variable would include the period of relatively low disappearance 1J1 the early—19808. Again, tjuazmost obvious change occurs after 1983. In Table 7.6, the analysis is taken one step further by examining more closely the shifts in slope coefficients aCross time periods. However, the only significant cross—product is one which represents the product of the firm failure rate and the post-1983 period. In the previous chapter, it was seen 215 that there was large increase in the magnitude of firm failures after~ 1983, which, no «doubt, accounts for this result. But while the positive coefficient for the post—1983 cross—product is largely cancelled out by the negative coefficient (H? the independent effect (M3 the firm failure variable. If the firm failure variable controlling for time period would have been positive and significant, and the cross—product had been positive and significant, an argument could have been made for the increasing saliency of the variable over time. But with oppositely signed coefficients this does not appear to be the case. Such a strong cancellation does not occur, however, with the variable for cross—state change which remains significant as a positive predictor of unit disappearance, and whose cross—product, while negatively signed, is not significant (nor even close to significant). In fact, in Model 6 the inclusion of the cross—products causes the cross—state distribution variable itself to become even. more highly significant (Table 7.6). All. of these coefficients. are somewhat difficult to interpret because, an; Blalock (1961, g). 125) noted: "The magnitude of rxy will depend not only in the size of the slope but also (M1 the change 1J1 X relative t1) that iJ11nuisance variables such as U, V, and W." In Model 3 (Table 7.5), the time period dummy variable is clearly significant. However, 216 in Model 6 (Table 7.6), the time period dummy variable is (just barely) non—significant. This does suggest that the chumm/ variable, (M: least partially, nesks tine interaction effects of the time period and (most likely) firm failure rates, so that some of the impact of time period itself may be explained by the increases in firm failures for the period. For the rmxfi: part, establishment growth anxi capital intensity remained significant. Regardless of enn/ of the other effects, disappearances were most likely to occur in labor intensive industries that were reducing the number of establishments. 217 TABLE 7.6. Standardized regression coefficients with period effects and cross- products, lagged model, t—values in parentheses, N:56. Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Establishment Growth -.3797** -.6834*** -.5767*** (-1.82) (-3.84) (-2.88) Firm Failures -.2523 -1.705** .1532 (1.38) (-2.33) (.52) Capital Intensity -.2988 -.6043*** -.4503** (-1.67) (-3.82) (-2.36) New Capital Investment -.2984 -.1377 -.7232** (-.32) (-.32) (—2.47) Decertification Rate .1226 -.1811 .1825 ( .16) (—.51) ( .66) Union Penetration Rate -.0379 -.1020 .0810 (-.17) (-.56) (.39) Small Firm Growth .0560 -.0137 .1122 ( .07) (-.05) (.44) Cross-State Change .1813 .6636** .1712 (.60) (2.22) (.85) Employment Growth .0484 -.0415 .0523 (.18) ( .19) (.20) After 1980 .7681 (.92) After 1983 .9414 (1.54) After 1986 1.4231 (1.31) Firm Failure x Period Effect NA 2.0446* -1.1545 (1.76) (~1.21) Cross State Change x Period Effect -.4441 -.5925 .3058 (-.69) (-.76) (.43) Small Firm Growth x Period Effect .0566 -.1919 -.0180 (.07) (-.69) (-.08) New Capital Investment X Period Effect .0435 -.2297 .2602 ( .05) (-.56) (1.10) Decertification x Period Effect -.2038 -.0766 -.4131 (-.21) (-.15) (-.78) R’ .42 .64*** .50* Adj R' .13 .45 .23 F value 1.47 3.34 1.88 D.M. 2.06 1.93 2.20 ***p.<.001, **p.<.05. *p.<.10 To appreciate better the story being told by the regression results, it is helpful to examine changes in R2 particularly adjusted R3 across the models. Rzindicates the amount of variance explained by a regression model and can always be inflated by adding more variables to the model. However, an inefficient inflation of R3 comes at the expense of significance, since degrees of freedom are sacrificed for little improvement in model fit. But when additional variables add very little to the amount of variance explained by a model, adjusted R3 the LUUtMi movement. The administration was generally successful in seating its nominees due to Republican control of the Senate. Following the appointment of a solid conservative majority—~Dotson4 Hunter, and. Dennis-~by Dmn/ of 1983, an unprecedented number of doctrinal reversals were issued. One roadblock to the total overhaul remained in William Lubbers, 237 who was to hold the General Counsel’s position until 1984. Chairman Dotson, therefore, sought to circumvent Lubbers——to the extent statutorily possible—~by rescinding the General Counsel’s 30 year control over the enforcement process, and placing that responsibility with the Board Solicitor. At the time, the Solicitor was Hugh Reilly, who had once worked for the legal arm of the National Right-to-Work Committee. Following the expiration of Lubbers’s tern» the General Counsel’s job went to Rosemary Collyer, also a former management advocate——though more recently'a memberciftimeMine Safety’ Commission—~over the vigorous opposition. of labor leaders. Between 1983 and 1986, the Board reversed several dozen precedents. For current purposes the most important cases were Otis Elevator II, Milwaukee Spring II,.Machinists Local 1414, Rossmore House, and several progeny of the 1982 Midland National Life decision (for example, Pilliord of Mississippi and Atlantic Forest Products). Through these reversals, the Board narrowed an employers duty tm> bargain over business decisions affecting the bargaining unit, made it more difficult for unions to promulgate standards of membership, and further deregulated conduct during certification elections. These changes may have put local collective bargaining relationships at greater risk by lowering the costs to the 238 employer associated with escaping unionization, by making it more difficult for unions to act against dissident members, and by allowing employers to have greater influence over the outcome of the decertification process. This conjecture is further substantiated by the quantitative results which indicate changes iii the explanation (n5 unit disappearance after 1983. B. Discussion. This research raises a number of issues that transcend the specific research hypotheses and time period studied: the proper role of the state in the industrial relations system, the stability of labor relations doctrine, and the extent to which the stability of doctrine affects the stability of the industrial relations system. F m mostcflfits history, industrial relations scholarship had been concerned primarily with the relationship between employers and the representatives of employees (Kaufman, 1993). In “weak state" nations snmfliems the United States (Skocpol, 1985), it is not clear what the role of the state has been, is, or should be in the industrial relations system. Older conceptualizations indicate an early divergence between the government and the system’s principals. Commons (1918, ;p. 9) writes: By vetoing the laws which labour in its political struggles has been able to secure, the courts, joined to divergent 239 state policies, have excluded or delayed labor from legislative influence. Consequently, the energies of organization are turned to the economic field...In this way has our Federal and judicial system of government added its pressure on labour and forced it to acquire kn/ trade infirm) action vflmm; in other countries has been granted by legislation. Perlman (1928, p. 170) picking up on the same point, adds: Obviously, then, American governments are inherently inadequate as instruments of economic reform... It is to this situation, more than anything else that the stubborn economism of the American Federation of Labor must be traced. Both Commons and Perlman argue that reliance on the state was largely unavailable to labor movement at the earliest stages of its development because of the patchwork of local laws and an unreceptive judiciary. Therefore, after having been (an; off from time state, industrial relations developed as a "voluntary" system relying, instead, on collective bargaining between employers and local unions. Recently, critical legal scholars (Klare, 1981; Forbath, 1989) have taken a somewhat different view. They argue that late into the 19th century the AFL and the Knights of Labor continued to press for state action. All over the country, Knights’ candidates ran for local office, and within the AFL a fairly large Lassallean wing formed local labor parties. 240 Sometimes these political efforts were successful, but on a larger scale the relations between labor and the state were hostile as the use of the labor injunction became widespread. Hence, the state was still very much a pdayer, but nearly always to the benefit of employers. The system was not as "voluntaristic" as Commons and Perlman assert. After passage of the Clayton, Norris—Laguardia, Railway Labor, Wagner, and Taft—Hartley Acts, it was impossible to deny the active participation of the state in the system. In John Dunlop’s classic Industrial Relations Systems (1958) government was counted as an "actor" in the system equal in status to labor and management. Two years later, Kerr, Dunlop, Harbison, and Myers (1960, p. 25) were to write: Governments have 61 significant role iii determining the substantive rules of the work. community bargain enmi technology. Workplace Topics. 3(1): 55—66. Sockell, Donna. 1989. The future of labor law: a mismatch between statutory' interpretation. and :reality? Boston College Law Review. 50: 987—1026. Sockell, Donna. 1986. The scope of mandatory bargaining: a critique auui proposal. Industrial auui Labor Relations Review. 40: 19—34. Sockell, Donna and John Thomas Delaney. 1986. Who wins if fewer items and mandatory subjects of bargaining? Labor Studies Journal. 11: 101—116. Sockell, Donna and John Thomas Delaney. 1987. Union organizing and the Reagan NLRB. Contemporary Policy Issues. 5: 28— 45. Sommers, Albert T. 1993. The'U.S. Economy Demystified, 3rd ed. New York: Lexington Books. Somson, Barbara. 1984. Duty to bargaing over plant closings relocations: a union. view. ‘Willianl Dolson and Kent Lollis, eds., First Annual Labor and Employment Law Institute. Littleton, CO: Fred B. Rothman and Co. pp. 155-180. 269 Steffen, John F. 1989. The work preservation exception to sections 8(b)(4)(B) éUKi 8(e) ‘as a: means tx) control technology caused worker displacement: a doctrine whose utility has come and gone. Detroit College of LaW'Review. 3: 1133—1174. Stepina, Lee and Jack Fiorito. 1986. Toward a comprehensive theory<3finfirxigrowth.and«decline. Industrial Relations. 25: 248—264. Stone, Katherine Van Wezel. 1981. The post—war paradigm in American labor law. The Yale Law Journal. 90: 1509—1580. Storper; Michael and. Richard lMalker. 1984. The spatial division of labor: labor and the location of industries. Larry Sawers and William K. Tabb, eds. Sunbelt/Snowbelt New York: Oxford University Press. Stryker, Robin. 1989. Limits on technocratization of the law: the elimination of the National Labor Relations Board Division (fl? Economic Research. American Sociologial Review 54: 341—358. Summers, Clyde. 1965. Labor law in the Supreme Court. Yale Law Journal. 75: 59—88. Tomlins, Christopher 1;. 1985. The State enui the 'Unions. Cambridge: Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Tomlins, Christopher 1;. 1985a. The ruwv deal, collective bargaining, and time triumph CHE industrial pfluralism. Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 39:19-34. Troy, Leo. 1990. Is the U.S. unique in the decline of private sector unionism?. Journal of Labor Research. 9: 111—143. Troy, Leo. 1969. Trade union growth and the changing economy. Monthly Labor Review 92: 3—7. Trumka, Richard L. 1987. Why labor law has failed. West Virginia Law Review. 89: 871—882. Tuma, Nancy B., Hannan, Michael T. and Lyle P. Groeneveld. 1979. Dynamic analysis of event histories. American Journal of Sociology. 84: 820-854. 270 General Accounting Office. 1986. U.S. Business Closures and Permanent Layoffs During 1983 and 1984. Washington, D.C: GPO. House (ME Representatives. 1988. Hearings before the Committeeeon Goverment Operations. 1988 Oversight of the National Labor Relation Board. July 13. Washington D.C: GPO. House CHE Representatives. 1987. Hearings before the Committee on‘Goverment Operations. 1987 Oversight of the National Labor Relation Board. July 21. Washington D.C: GPO. Iknmxa of Representatives. 1986. Hearings before the Committee (n1 Goverment Operations. Oversight (Hi the National Labor Relation BoardL Part 2. July 17. Washington D.C: GPO. House CNS Representatives. 1985. Hearings before the Committee (M1 Goverment cmmxations. Oversight (Hi the National Labor Relation Board. June 18. Washington D.C: GPO. . House of.Representatives. 1984. Joint hearings before the Committees on Education and Labor and Government Operations. Oversight hearings on the Subject "Has Labor Law Failed?" June 21, 25 and 26. Washington, D.C: GPO. House of Representatives. 1984a. The Failure of Labor Law: A Betrayal of American Workers. Washington, D.C.: GPO. House of Representatives. 1984b. Hearings before the Committee on Goverment Operations. National Labor Relation Board Case Backlog, Part 2. May 9. Washington D.C: GPO. . House of Representatives. 1983. Joint hearings before the Committees on Education and Labor and Government Operations. CNersight CH1 the Rational Imfixnr Relation Board. June 15 and 29. Washington, D.C: GPO. House of Representatives. 1983a. Hearings before the Committee on Goverment Operations. National Labor Relation Board Case Backlog. November 2. Washington D.C: GPO. 271 U.S. House of Representatives. 1976. Hearings before the Committee on Education and Labor. Oversight on the National Labor Relation Act. February 17, 19; March 15, 16, 22, 29, 30, 31; April 6, 7; May 3, 4, and 5. Washington, D.C: GPO. U.S. House of Representatives. 1975. Hearings before the Committee on Education and Labor. Oversight on the National Labor Relation Board. ihflqr 15; October, 23; November 13enuil8; Novemeber 216NK122. Washington, D.C: GPO. U.S. Senate. 1987. Committee on Labor and Human Resources. Hearings on the Economic Dislocation and Worker Assistance Act of 1987. mashington, D.C.: Government Printing Office. Walther, Peter D. 1985. The NLRB today. Labor Law Journal. 36: 803—816. Wren, John and Kent Murrman. 1990. Chapter 11 and collective bargaining agreements. Employee Relations Law Journal. 16(1): 17—27. Verma, Anil and Thomas A. Kochan. 1985. The growth and nature of the nonunion sector within a firm. T. Kochan, ed., Challenges and Choices Facing American Labor. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. pp. 89—118. Visser, Jelle. 1988. Trade unionism in Europe: present situation and prospects. Labor and Society. 13: 125-182. Wallace, Michael and Joyce Rothschild. 1988. Plant closings, capital flight, and worker dislocation: the long shadow of deindustrialization. Researtl1in Politics and.Society. 3: 1-35. Walton, Richard, Cutcher-Gershenfeld, Joel and Robert McKersie. 1994. Strategic Negotiations. Boston: Harvard Business Press. Watanabe, S. 1971. Subcontracting, industrialisation and employment creation. International Labour Review. 105: 425-449. Weber, Arnold. 1961. The Structure of Collective Bargaining. Glencoe, IL: Free Press. 272 Wendling, Wayne. 1984. The Plant Closure Policy Dilemma. Kalamazoo, MI: Upjohn Institute. Weikle, R.D. and H. Wheeler. 1984, Unions and technological change: attitudes and local union leaders. Proceedings of the Thirty—Sixth Annual Meeting. Madison, WI: IRRA. Wieler, Paul. 1990. Governing the Workplace. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Wieler, Paul. 1983. Promises to keep: securing workers’ rights to self—organization under the NLRA. Harvard Law Review. 96: 418—476. Winter, Ralph. 1968. Judicial review of agency decisions: the labor board and the court. Supreme Court Review 53. 273 Wheeler, Hoyt and Lkflni A, McClendon. 1991. The individual decision to unionize. G. Strauss, D. Gallagher and J. Fiorito, eds., fflua State of time Unions. Madison, WI: IRRA. pp. 47-84. Yamaguchi, Kazuo. 1991. Event History Analysis. Newbury Park, Ca.: Sage Publishing. Zidich, Debra J. 1984. Robotics in the workplace: the employers duty to bargain over its implementation and effect on the worker. Santa Clara Law Review. 24: 917— 945. MIC $111111: