m. 13‘ u - : 5&3‘sggfig 2k 55. \ . 3:1!» . “f 1‘6 ' ' ‘H‘Lf'xsa u ”fiflfgfi ‘i I‘5. v . x .I' . a . '5. Via: a 04 g LIBRARIES \\\\\\\l illllllljil w \\\\\\\\\\\\\\\\ This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Impacts of Urbanization on Agricultural Development in the Northern Coastal Region of West Java, Indonesia presented by Joyo Winoto has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph . D . degree in Resource Development ( ' I r / . [1' CfiJ-l/u/ //jlc.( L Major professor 4.: Date 2-20—95 MS U i: an Affirmative Acri'on/ Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE DI RETURN BOXtonmovothb chockoutflun yourrocord. TO AVOID FINES Mum on or before an. duo. IMPACTS OF URBANIZATION ON AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT IN THE NORTHERN COASTAL REGION OF WEST JAVA, INDONESIA By Joyo Winoto A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Resource Development 1995 iii-“i .‘F- .o- ABSTRACT IMPACTS OF URBANIZATION ON AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT IN THE NORTHERN COASTAL REGION OF WEST JAVA, INDONESIA By Joyo Winoto Current regional development strategy in the North Coastal Region of West Java (NCR) has favored urban development. Urbanization, in pan induced by the strategy, is expected to put additional pressure on the sustainability of agriculture in the region—the ”bread basket" of Indonesia. More importantly, urbanization process is also expected to negatively affect 76 percent (1992) of the rural population engaged in agriculture. This thesis analyzes the regional urbanization process and its causal factors, its relationship with regional development, and its impacts on agricultural development to suggest alternative policy interventions needed to sustain a viable (regional) agricultural sector. The study employed three sets of data: primary data collected at the village level for the period of 1982-1992, secondary data derived from the Census of 1980 and 1990, and secondary data provided by the Project of Land Conversion in Java. Urbanization in the region was caused mostly by economic stress in nual agricultural areas rather than increased economic opportunities in the urban areas. The rate of regional urbanization was higher in urban than in rural areas, indicating a cumulative causation process or self-reinforcing process of urbanization. J oyo Winoto Urbanization has increased agricultural land parcelization, landless farming households, absentee agricultural land ownership, and agricultural land conversion to non- agricultural uses. Urbanization has also displaced self-employed farmers to agricultural laborers and small scale enterprises. Existing regional development strategies have created rural-urban disparities expressed as measures of economic progress and the provision of public facilities. Urbanization, therefore, has negatively affected the viability of regional agriculture and its role as the bread basket of Indonesia, and the welfare of the rural population engaged in the agricultural sector. To sustain regional agriculture and to overcome the negative impacts of urbanization on the welfare of rural populations and rural-urban disparities, in the short-term, the government must change investment strategies from a focus on urban sectors and areas to diversion of investments over space to promote the establishment of generative, secondary cities in the region. In the mid-term, the government must also provide greater local autonomy, at least, by fostering land use planning initiatives which incorporate policy measures with incentives to rural populations engaged in agriculture such as creating transferable land development rights, agricultural tax abatements, subsidies in agricultural inputs and marketing, and public investments in the rural infrastructure. Copyright by JOYO WINOTO 1995 To Leila, Larasita, Bapak, Ibuk, and Petani Indonesia ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I gratefully acknowledge the contribution of individuals and institutions both in the US and Indonesia that have made this dissertation possible. First of all, I would like to express many thanks to Dr. Gerhardus Schultink, Professor, Department of Resource Development, Michigan State University, who served as my dissertation director and advisor during my course work. His friendly advice and continual encouragement throughout my entire graduate program and his stamina in reviewing a great many drafts were instrumental to the successful completion of this dissertation. His fatherly advice, patience, and encouragement have strengthened my commitment to the science and its use for those who are powerless. I would also like to thank Dr. Assefa Mehretu, Professor in Economic Geography and Integrated Study in Social Science; Dr. James Bingen, Professor, Department of ' Resource Development; and Dr. Richard H. Bernsten, Professor, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University for serving in my dissertation committee and for their extremely valuable comments in this study. Special thanks is expressed to Dr. Mehretu who taught me not only how to learn but also how to teach efl‘ectively in the enjoyable environment. Research funding was obtained from several sources. I wish to thank Dr. Agus Pakpahan, Center for Agro Economic (PAE), Ministry of Agriculture, Indonesia who gave me an opportunity to incorporate this research in his on-going project of land conversion in Java. Special thanks is expressed to Ir. Soemaryanto, M8,, project manager, and his stafl‘ who provided me with full access to project data. This research could not been completed without personal, financial, and logistical supports from Dr. Lutfi Ibrahim Nasoetion, Director of the Research Institute, Bogor Agricultural University, Indonesia. In addition, Dr. Nasoetion was also my academic advisor in Bogor Agricultural University who encouraged me to pursue my graduate studies in the Department of Resource Development, Michigan State University. For all his support and encouragement, I would like to express my deep appreciation. Additional funding for field research in Indonesia was provided by International Studies and Programs, the Department of Resource Development, and the Thoman Fellow Program, Michigan State University. Specifically, I wish to thank Dr. Gil-Chin Lim, Dean of the International Studies and Programs; Dr. Gerhardus Schultink; and Dr. James Bingen who made the in-country survey possible. Special thanks is also due to the several people who helped me complete this dissertation. Dyah Retno Panuju, Suhadak, and Daud from the Department of Soil Sciences, Bogor Agricultural University, helped me collect field data with full eagerness although without any financial rewards. Erlin from the Research Institute Office, Bogor Agricultural University, facilitated my field research because of her skills in handling all administrative requirements. Ali Nurmansyah and Rahayu Riana helped me clarify some statistical concepts. I would also to thank Herr Soeryantono who helped me improve my computer skills and helped organize my dissertation. Most importantly, I thank him and his family for their commitment and for life-long fiiendship. vii I would also like to express my gratitude to Proyek Pengembangan Staf dan Sarana Perguruan Tinggi (Proyek PSZPT), Ministry of Education and Culture, Indonesia for financially supporting my graduate studies at Michigan State University. A special word of thanks to Dr. Sitanala Arsyad, Professor and Rector of Bogor Agricultural University, who made it possible to take a study leave for five years. Also, a special thanks to Dr. Oetit Koswara, Professor, Department of Soil Sciences, Bogor Agricultural University who helped me obtain a full scholarship from the Ministry of Education and Culture, Indonesia. Special thank also due to Dr. Muslimin Nasution, Assistant for the Minister of Central Bureau of Planning and Development, for his personal support during my graduate studies. Finally, I want to thank my wife, Leila, to whom I remain forever grateful for her love, support, and patience. I cannot thank my daughter, Larasita, enough for traveling accross the seas and thousands miles to permit me to conduct field research at her age of 26 days. Moreover, Larasita's laughs and cries are part of the excitement in finalizing this dissertation. My father and my mother who always support and pray for my success must receive the highest recognition. Special thanks to my older brother, Ir. Soeryo Handoko, who always loves me and has financially supported me during the field research. Special thanks also to my beloved sister in law, Tieke, who helped me finalize this dissertation by staying in the US during the process of writing and helped me type some tables. More importantly for her patience in taking care of my daughter while I was absorbed in the writing of this dissertation. viii TABLE OF CONTENTS PAGE LIST OF TABLE .................................................................................................. xii LIST OF FIGURES ............................................................................................... xv ABBREVIATIONS ............................................................................................. xvii CHAPTER I. Introduction ......................................................................................................... l 1.1. Background of the Study .............................................................................. 1 1.2. Problem Statement ....................................................................................... 6 1.2.1. The Northern Coastal Region of West Java NCR : Regional Characteristics and Policies Afi‘ecting Agricultural Development and Urbanization .......................................................... 6 1.2.2. Research Problems ........................................................................... 14 1.3. Research Objectives ................................................................................... 17 1.4. Organization of Dissertation ....................................................................... 18 II. Impacts of Urbanization on Agricultural Development : A Conceptual F rarnework ....................................................................................................... 20 2.1. Key Concepts and Definitions .................................................................... 20 2.1.1. Urbanization .................................................................................... 20 2.1.2. Agricultural Development ................................................................ 24 2.2. Impacts of Urbanization on Agricultural Development in the NCR ............. 31 2.2.1. Urbanization and Regional Development .......................................... 31 2.2.2.1. Urbanization : Modernization and Dependency Theories ..... 32 2.2.2.2. Urbanization Theory in the LDC's ....................................... 36 2.2.2. Rural Urban Interactions .................................................................. 40 2.2.3. Impacts of Urbanization and Agricultural Development in the NCR : A General Hypothesis ..................................................... 43 2.2.4. Specific Research Hypotheses ...................................... ' .................... 48 III. Data Collection and Research Methods ............................................................. 51 3.1. Data Collection Method ............................................................................. 51 3.1.1. Primary Data .................................................................................... 52 3.1.1.1. Sampling Procedures ........................................................... 54 3.1.1.2. Survey Instnrments ............................................................. 56 3.1.2. Secondary Data ................................................................................ 57 3.2. Compilation and Organization of Data ........................................................ S8 3.3. Data Analysis ............................................................................................. 58 3.3.1. Steps of Data Analysis ..................................................................... 58 3 .32. Mathematical Models ...................................................................... 59 3.3.2.1. Rate of Change in Population Density Over Time ................ 59 3.3.2.2. Rate of Change in Population Density Over Space .............. 60 3.3.2.3. Urbanization Process Analysis ............................................. 62 3.3.2.4. Location Quotients and Gini Coefficients ............................ 64 3.3.2.5. Sample Mean Comparisons ................................................. 66 IV. Urbanization and Its Causal Factors .................................................................. 69 4.1. Urbanization in the NCR ............................................................................ 70 4.1.1. Rural-Urban Classification ............................................................... 70 4.1.2. Level of Urbanization ....................................................................... 72 4.1.3. Temporal and Spatial Rate of Change in Population Density ............. 79 4.1.3.1. Temporal Rate of Change in Population Density ................ 79 4.1.3.2. Spatial Rate of Change in Population Density ..................... 83 4.2. Urbanization Process in the NCR ............................................................... 88 4.2.]. Definition of Urbanization Process and Its Causal Factors ................ 88 4.2.2. Factors Determining Urbanization Process in the NCR ..................... 95 4.2.2.1. Push Factors ..................................................................... 102 4.2.2.1.1. Changes in Land Tenure .................................... 102 4.2.2.1.2. Changes in the Agricultural Economy ................ 104 4.2.2.2. Pull Factors ....................................................................... 106 4.2.2.2. 1. The Degree of Industrial Development .............. 106 4.2.2.2.2. Changes in the Availability of Public Facilities ........................................................... 107 4.2.2.2.3. Changes in the Availability of Pre-college Educational Development ................................. 108 4.2.2.3. Demographic Factors ........................................................ 109 4.2.3. Village Proximity to Cities and Urbanization Process ..................... 109 V. Urbanization and Agricultural Development ..................................................... 115 5.1. Operational definitions ............................................................................. 117 5.2. Changes in the Distribution of Regional Land Ownership ......................... 119 5.2.1. Changes of Land Ownership Distribution in the NCR Region ........................................................................................... 119 5.2.2. Changes of Land Ownership Distribution in Rural Areas ................ 121 5.3. Absentee Land Ownership in Rural Areas and the NCR Region ................ 124 5.3.1. Absentee Land Ownership in the NCR Region ............................... 125 5.3.2. Absentee Land Ownership in Rural Areas ....................................... 127 5 .4. Agricultural Land Conversion in Rural Areas and in the NCR Region ....... 129 5.4.1. Agricultural Land Conversion in the NCR Region .......................... 130 5.4.2. Agricultural Land Conversion in Rural Areas ................................. 132 5.5. Impacts of Agricultural Land Conversion on Household Income .............. 133 5.6. Structural Changes in Regional and Rural Village Employment ................ 136 X VI. Regional Development of the Northern Coastal Region of West Java (NCR) ............................................................................................................ 143 6.1. Regional Development of the NCR .......................................................... 143 6.2. Rural-Urban Disparities ............................................................................ 146 6.2.1. Regional Economic Progress .......................................................... 148 6.2.2. Marketing Facilities ........................................................................ 153 6.2.3. Educational Facilities ..................................................................... 157 6.2.4. Health Care Facilities ..................................................................... 160 VII. Summary and Policy Implications .................................................................. 163 7.1. Summary of Findings ............................................................................... 166 7.2. Policy Implications ................................................................................... 176 7.3. Needs for Further Research ..................................................................... 181 BIBLIOGRAPHY ................................................................................................ 183 LIST OF TABLES TABLE PAGE 1. Number of Villages in the Northern Coastal Region of West Java (NCR) by Population Density Interval in 1980 and 1990 ............................... 73 2. Number of Rural and Urban Villages in the NCR in 1980 and 1990 .............. 75 3. Changing Composition of Rural and Urban Population in the NCR in 1980 and 1990 .............................................................................................. 76 4. Mean of Rate of Change in Population Density between 1980 and 1990 (TRCPD) in the Northern Coastal Region of West Java ....................... 81 5. Mean Comparison of the Temporal Rate of Change in Population Density (TRCPD) among Sub-regions in the NCR Using One Way Anova and Least-significant Different (LSD) Multiple Range Tests .............. 82 6. Rate of Change in Population Density (b) Over Distance (SRCPD) from the Capital City of Kabupaten Using Linear Model with Least Square Method ............................................................................................. 85 7. List of Causal Factors Expected to Affect Regional Urbanization .................. 90 8. Trends of Causal Factors Expected to Affect Regional Urbanization ............ 96 9. Causal Regional Urbanization Factors ........................................................... 99 10. Statistical Summary of the Multiple Regressions of Urbanization with Distance factors in the NCR ........................................................................ 1 1 1 11. Statistical Summary of the Multiple Regressions of the Urbanization Process in the NCR with Dummy Variables of Urban Area and Urban Area with the Village Proximity to Jakarta, Cirebon, and to the Capital City of Kabupaten ....................................................................................... 11 1 12. Differences in the Distribution of Household Land Ownership in the NCR between 1982 and 1992 ..................................................................... 120 13. Differences in the Distribution of Household Land Ownership in the Rural Areas of the NCR between 1982 and 1992 ........................................ 122 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. Regional Differences in the Hectarage of Absentee Lands and the Total Number of Absentee Land Owners or Absentee Landlords between 1982 and 1992 .............................................................................. 125 Differences in the Hectarage of Absentee Lands and the Total Number of Absentee Land Owners or Absentee Landlords in the Rural Areas of the NCR between 1982 and 1992 ........................................................... 128 Differences in the Total Land (ha) and Total Land for Each 1,000 Village Population (ha/1,000 village population) for both Irrigated Land and Agricultural Dryland in the NCR between 1982 and 1992 ........... 131 Differences in the Total Land (ha) and Total Land for Each 1,000 Village Population (ha/1,000 village population) for both Irrigated Land and Agricultural Dryland in the Rural Areas of NCR between 1982 and 1992 ............................................................................................ 132 Difi‘erences in On-farm, Ofilfarm, and Total Incomes (Rupiah) of Farming Households Before and After Irrigated Land Conversion During the Period of 1982 and 1992 ........................................................... 134 Difi‘erences between A fler-Land-Conversion-On-farm Income of the Households Involved in Land Conversion and On-farm Income of Those not Involved in Land Conversion, 1992 ............................................ 136 Differences in the Regional and Rural Area's Employment Structure between 1982 and 1992 .............................................................................. 137 Differences in Regional Industrialization between 1982 and 1992 ................ 144 Location Quotients, Gini Coefficients, Percentage Distribution of the Number of Telephones, Houses with Electricity, Television, and Population by Village; and Data for Lorenz Curves in the NCR, 1990 ........ 150 Location Quotients, Gini Coefficients, Percentage Distribution of Village Marketing Facilities including Number of Markets with Permanent Buildings, Kiosks selling Agricultural Inputs, Kiosks selling Agricultural Products, and Population; and Data for Lorenz Curves in the NCR, 1990 ........................................................................................... 155 24. Location Quotients, Gini Coefficients, Percentage Distribution of 25. Village Educational facilities including Number of Elementary Schools, Secondary Schools, High School, and Population; and Data for Lorenz Curves in the NCR, 1990 .......................................................... 158 Location Quotients, Gini Coeflicients, Percentage Distribution of Village Availability of Health Care Facilities including Number of Physician, Traditional Midwives, Health Care Providers, and Population; and Data for Lorenz Curves in the NCR 1990 ......................... 161 xiv LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE PAGE 1. Java Islands and Its Provinces ......................................................................... 3 2. Study Area : the Northern Coastal Region of West Java (NCR) which consists of Kabupatens Bekasi, Karawang, Subang, and lndramayu ................ 7 3. Distribution of the Villages in the NCR Based on the Village's Population Density ....................................................................................... 73 4. Distribution of Rural and Urban Villages in the NCR in 1980 and 1990 ......... 75 5. Total Population in Each Sub-region (RI-4; U1-4) of the NCR for 1980 and 1990 .............................................................................................. 76 6. Mean of Rate of Change in Population Density in Each Sub-region (R1-4',U1-4)ofthe NCR between 1980 and 1990 ........................................ 81 7. Distance Decay Function of Population Density from the Capital City of Kabupatens Bekasi, Karawang, Subang, Indrarnayu, and in the NCR in 1990 ................................................................................................ 8S 8. The Relationship between the Actual Values of the Natural Log of Village's Population Density and Its Predicted Values Derived from the Analysis .................................................................................................. 87 9. Functional Linkages Among Urbanization, Its Causal Factor, and Agricultural Development ........................................................................... 116 10. Lorenz Curves for the Distribution of the Households with Telephone, Electricity, and with Television in Relation to Population, by Sub— regions of the NCR ..................................................................................... 150 11. Lorenz Curves for the Distribution of Markets with Permanent Buildings, Kiosks selling Agricultural Inputs, and Kiosks selling Agricultural Products in Relation to Population, by Sub-regions of the NCR ........................................................................................................... 155 12. Lorenz Curves for the Distribution of the Number of Elementary 13. Schools, Secondary Schools, and High Schools in Relation to Population, by Sub-regions of the NCR ...................................................... 158 Lorenz Curves for the Distribution of the Number of Physician, Midwives, and Total Health Care Providers in Relation to Population, by Sub-regions of the NCR ......................................................................... 161 ABBREVIATION Organizations GOI Government of Indonesia CBS Central Bureau of Statistics PLN Perusahaan Listrik Negara, a government agency providing electricity in Indonesia PAE Pusat Penelitian Sosial Ekonomi Pertanian (the Center for Agro Economic Research) IPB Institut Pertanian Bogor (Bogor Agricultural University) Technical Terms NCR The Northern Coastal Region of West Java, the study area R1-4 Sub-region 1 to 4 of the rural area Ul-4 Sub-region 1 to 4 of the urban area UP Urbanization process in the NCR TRCPD Temporal Rate of Change in Population Density (people/kmzlyear) SRCPD Spatial Rate of Change in Population Density (people/ka/km) GC Gini Coefficient, an index of dissimilarity LQ Location Quotient, an index of concentration LSI Large Scale Industry (2 100 employees) MSI Medium Scale Industry (20 5 employees < 100) S81 Small Scale Industry (5 5 employees < 20) Phone Telephones Elect. Electricity, households with electricity TV Television KAI Kiosks selling agricultural inputs KAP Kiosks selling agricultural products Elsch Elementary school Secsch Secondary school Hisch High school Mwife Traditional midwives Care Total health care providers including hospitals, polyclinics, clinics, maternity centers, and community health care centers Anova Analysis of Variance LSD Least-significant Difference D.F. Degree of Freedom m Meter km2 Square kilometer (1,000 m x 1,000 m) haorHA Hectare(100mx100m) C Celcius Rp. Rupiah, Indonesian currency unit xvii I. INTRODUCTION 1.1. Study Background In the last two decades, Indonesia has experienced fast-growing urban population. It is predicted that almost forty million residents will be added to Indonesia's cities in the final two decades of this century (Hamer, Steer, and Williams, 1986). Most of this urban population is concentrated in the most populous island of Indonesia, Javal (Moochtar, 1992; Soegijoko, 1992; Soemarwoto, 1992', Firman, 1992; Hill, 1992a; Hill, 1992b; Soernarwoto er a], 1991; Hardjono, 1983; Hugo, 1978). The recent census shows that 62 percent of the Indonesian population is concentrated on Java which covers only 7 percent of Indonesian's territory (Poot, Kuyvenhoven, and Johnson, 1990; Hill, 1992a). The total urban population in Java, in 1980, was 23 million people or 69.70 percent of the total urban population in Indonesia. The World Bank estimates that the total urban population in Java will rise to 41 million in the year of 20001. From this figure, Jakarta— the capital city of Indonesia—has the highest proportion of urban population in Java at 26.46 percent, followed by West Java province at 25.17 percent. Excluding Jakarta, West immuammmpmdbymmmranmummmfiwumumdsormmmm JayermauanaMandJm Amongtheceislands,Javaisthemostpqnflousmddevelopedislandinthc country. Javaisusuaflycafledasaninnaislandandotherislmsmcanedoutaialmds. Arhninistratively,.lavais dividedbySprovincecarnong27provinceainIndoneaia. 'l'hepcvincecinJavaare:(i)theapecialprovinceof Jakata;(ii)flrermvinceofWectJava;(iii)thepmvinceofCentralJava;(iv)thecpccialprovinceonogyakarta;and (v)theprovinceofEastJava(Figm-el) ZMMWmm-mmmmdmmmmmmwmmsrmm. Thisassmnptionwillmakethereaultofthepmjectionisexpectedto \mdaeatirnatetherealrn'banpopulationgrowth becauaeof:(1)theincreaseofthedynamicofnnal-mbanmigrationasaremltofinfiasuucunedevelopmtinthe last15yeusinJavamchasthedevelcpmmtofhighwaysinJavaandahhedymicofeconomicdevelopmcntin theareasmrndbigcitieainJavaasstatedbyFirman(l992;p. 101) l 2 Java has the highest proportion of urban population in Java at 34.24 percent (Harner et al., 1986) concentrated in the northern coastal region (Hill, 1992b; Soegijoko, 1992; F irman, 1992) as a result of many economic activities especially industry, trade, and services, acting as engines of urbanization (Firman, 1992). The location of Java and its provinces are depicted below (Figure 1). In his study, Firman (1992) concludes that urban population growth in Java is not only evident in the big cities—such as Jakarta, Bandung, Cirebon, Semarang, and Surabaya—but also in: (i) the periphery of such big cities, and (ii) the areas close to the regional arterial roads connecting large cities. In other words, urbanization process in Javaoccursnotonlyintheareasaroundbigcitiesbutalsointhecorridorsjoininglarge cities, such as the area between Jakarta and Cirebon which is usually called as Jalur Pantar' Utara Jawa Barat or Northern Coastal Region of West Java (NCR). Urban population growth during the period 1980-1990 has created a growing corridor along the Northern coasts of Java, extending from Jakarta to Semarwrg through Cirebon (Firman, 1992; p. 104) Firman‘s finding confirms McGee's assertion that rapid urban growth in Asia is accompanied by the emergence of peri-urban regions and urbanized corridors joining big cities’ (McGee, 1991). McGee (1987 and 1990 cited in Firman, 1992; p. 96) identifies six characteristics of such urbanized corridors in Asia: (i) very high population density; (ii) generally but not exclusively wet-rice regions with very small landholdings; (iii) enveloping big cities in the regions; (iv) invariably characterized by growth of diverse non-agricultural 3McGee(1989)inhisartic1e, Urbau'sasiorKotadaasr'? .~ EvolvingPattmofUrbantzation inAsia, calledthe developmemofuhanizedregicnmchastheNCRasapmcessofkatadmsi. “Kamdeuriisacoinedmrdfin Mafihnhdmedalmmjdmkom(mwn)mddm(fiflage)mmakeupawdwm¢cufiuthe Wofmbanndnnlacfivityocanrmginfiresamegeographictantmy'McGee,1989,pp.93-94) A82 .55.: see 8582 ”00.89 8832.. a. as as? as. a same «$33.11.— eras—agar s. «>3. “we? 98 8: o a m meshes—om magnum @3er e as see .......... we... C On Eco—om 0...» e333. Fri-e? <~mmZOA—2— 4 activities; (v) there is considerable interaction between rural and urban activities; and (vi) with an intense land use mix. The study of the urbanization process in such a corridor region is a relatively new phenomenon in the literature of urbanization which usually focuses mainly on the dynamics of urban centers with analytical frameworks mostly fitting developed nations rather than developing nations‘ (Bhadra and Brandao, 1993; Datta, 1990). Several studies in urbanization in the developing nations, admittedly, have analyzed this type of region but theyusuallytreattheregionasasmallurbancenterwiththesamefirnctionsasthatofa large urban centers’ (Hardoy and Satterthwaite, 1986; Kabwegyere, 1979; Southall, 1979; Rondinelli and Ruddle, 1976; Hamer et a1, 1986; Armstrong, Warwick, and McGee, 1985; Bhooshan and Misra, 1980; Honjo, 1981; McAndrew, 1990). Moreover, the study concerning the impacts of urbanization on the agricultural development in both pen-urban and corridor regions is rarely conducted in the developing nations (Bhadra and Brandao, 1993), inchrding Indonesia (Firman, 1992). Consequently, the nature of urbanization and its impacts on rural and agricultural development in such urbanized corridors in Indonesia arenot firllyunderstood. 4BhadraandBrandao(1993;p.2)assertthat"I'heliteratrneanalyzingurbandeveloprnentislarge. Overthelast fundecadea,researchershavedealtwithmnnermsrelatedissues,suchaserquanationsfatheerdstenceandgrowth ddfiakmhfimsfipbmmcfiymwmmmmmmfimmdemcimmofmsector- medficmncaJvdhbihtymdmmmgmtdmmemmdmhdescmnmgbdamedmbm development.... Smprisingly,the1iteratrnehasgivenmnch1essattentimtotheimplicationsofm'bandevelopmem fateddamimfimoffiemoflmdflwfiimbflmnnflmdmhnmm,equivalently,between agricrrltmeandmagricultme. Maeover,mostoftheeadstingsmdiecfocuscnmedevelopedcmmniesandin particular,ontheUnited States”. Costaetal. (1989; p. 3), weaver, statesthat,’WhileAsianmbanization is dmilarinmyrespectstoWestantnbanizafionitisthedifi‘aunasweu'. slutheirarticle,WSnnllardlntamadiateUrbarCmm,l1ndoymdSanathwaite(l986;p. 6),fcrexamp1e, matethrn,”...theflamnbmaflahnamediatembmcartaswhichueflnwbmcmtaswithwhichmostm peopleandnrralarterpliaesinteract Yettherolethatsuehcenterscanplayinsupportingsocialandeconcmic development within rural areas...is rarely given sufficient attention". 5 Such regional growth complicates problems of regional development in Indonesia Until recently, Indonesia still does not have comprehensive measures to deal with urban development and agricultural development in the hinterlands of big cities (Harner et al, 1986). Therefore, macro and micro studies are needed to analyze the changes which occur in the urbanized corridors to permit the development of comprehensive regional planning in the future. Among them are studies to analyze: (i) the impacts of the changes on the regional development as a whole; (ii) the impacts of urbanization on agricultural development since agriculture is still the most important sector generating household and regional income, and employment; (iii) the changes in land use patterns and land prices in theareaimmediatelysurroundingmaincitiesaswellasintheruralareas;(iv)theextent of agriculturallanduseconversionanditsimpactsonthewelfareofthehouseholdsaudits impacts on agricultural sustainability; (v) the changes in relationships with the metropolitan centers; (vi) the changes in the socio-economic conditions in the region and the impacts on migration—both internal migration in the region and migration to the metropolitan centers; (vii) the changes in mral and urban employment; (viii) the changes in the settlement patterns; (ix) the changes in the environmental quality; (x) socio-economic dispmifiesbetweenmrflmdmbmareasofmeummcorndom;and(rd)flnchanges inmralanbanhnkageshtheareaandthechmgesinthembMuea-metropohnn center linkages. The suggested studies associated with the urbanized corridor, its characteristics, and processes listed by no means provide a complete list of research needs. Inthisstudy, someaspectsofthe changes ofthe corridorregion, especiallyimpacts of regional urbanization on agricultural development, are analyzed. 6 This study primarily analyzes the region that can be categorized as a corridor region joining large cities subject to urbanization with regional characteristics as those described by McGee (see pp. 2-4). Therefore, this study was conducted in Jalur Pantai Utara Jawa Barat or the Northern Coastal Region of West Java (NCR), connecting Jakarta and Cirebon. The NCR consists of four kabupatens‘5 , namely : (i) kabupaten Bekasi; (ii) kabupaten Karawang; (iii) kabupaten Subang; and (iv) kabupaten lndramayu (Figure 2). Thisisthemoa urbanized regioninJava(Firman, 1992)andhaslongbeendesignated as the bread basket of Indonesia (Soemarwoto, 1992). 1.2. Problem Statement The Northern Coastal Region of West Java (NCR) has long been the center of agricultural development , especially wet-rice production, in Indonesia". It is commonly referred to as the Iumbrmg pangon Indonesia or bread-basket of Indonesia (Soemarwoto, 1992). It has the best irrigation systems (Soemarwoto et al. 1991) and agricultural development institutions in Indonesia (Nasoetion, 1994). The development of this region asanagriculturalproducfioncemflcanbetracedbacktotheDtmhcolonial period. During this period, the development of the irrigation system along the NCR started. Following the independence of Indonesia in 1945, and continued by the New Order of 6mmumminimsvemtmdammmmormmm. lnhmmekecamatan Mofuvafldm,mneuamnmisuafivemitequivalanmavmagemtheUSsystem 7'AtWWofWeuhn'qumafimowmiumenmhanmregimwmchwlwmmcwmhdof thetctallmdareaoftheprovince'(HehanussaandHehuwat, 1979). 'I'heNCRisfmmedbyanalluviallowland It ccnaistslargelyof alluvial riverdepodtsandlaharsholcanic flowdeposits]&mnthevolcanoea(0ngkoscngo, 1979). Avu'ageannual rainfall isabout 1880mm(0ngkoscngo, 1979) with averagetanperannebetween27.1°and29.7°c (Ilahude,1979). 2 same “sesame assess an .meaasm $538“! ._m3_om 38333“ «e finance :02? 205 «>2. 50>» he eemwom 3300 552 ”32 lav—um ”N enema QZ in (upper tail), implies Ho: u; - u; 5 us, or mision Rule : RejectHoift<-tanorift>taafortwo-tailedtestwithCF : witness/n Reject Ho if t < 4,. for lower tail test with CF (confidence interval) : no i to Ss/n Rejecthift>taforuppertailtestwithCF(confidenceinterval):littlest/n To compare the characteristics of rural and urban areas, this study uses the t-test for two independent samples because the two population variances are not known. If the variances of the two populations are the same, sample variance 1 and sample variance 2 68 _ (nl—l)s,2+(n1-—1)s22 are combined using pooled variance, Si, , with degree of fieedom (nl—anZ—I) (df) of n + n l and t statistic of t ‘ fi- 75 In these uations X refers to l 2 Sle/nl+1/n2 ' eq ’ 1 sample 1 with number of sample n, and X refers to sample 2 with number of sample n; __ X' andthemeanoinscalculatedbe= 2" '. If the variances of the two populations are not the same, the t statistic used to test the it"i-Yi h thesis is t = . The d ee of fi'eedom for this case is we Jsf/nnsf/nz egr (S,2 /n1+S,2 /n2 df: (S ,2 lnl)2 /(rr1—1)+(S22 /n2)2 /(n2-l) ° IV. URBANIZATION AND ITS CAUSAL FACTORS This chapter describes the urbanization and its underlying causal factors in the Northern Coastal Region of West Java (NCR). The level of urbanization is described on the basis of the rural-urban classification described in Section 2.1.1 followed by the analysis of the rate of change in population density or the level of urbanization. In the analysis of urbanization process, regional pull and push factors are described in detail such that specific factors affecting the urbanization process can be identified. To analyze the urbanization process, the study treats the NCR as a single entity without disaggregating the region into administrative unit of kabupatens or into several agro-ecological zones. The NCR can be treated as a single entity since all four kabupatens in the region, according to Firman (1992) and Soemarwoto et al. (1991), have similar agricultural development problems afl‘ected by urbanization. In addition, at the Jakarta- West Java regional level, the NCR can be categorized as one agro—ecological zone since the existence of irrigated lands used for rice cultivation is ubiquitous in the region (Soemarwoto, 1992), the region consists of similar types of farm management (Erwidodo, 1990), the area is composed of alluvial lowlands (Ongkosongo, 1979), and there are no significant regional differences in rainfall and temperature with an average yearly rainfall of about 1880 mm and a temperature range from 27.1 to 29.7 °Celsius (Ongkosongo, 1979; Ilahude, 1979). Nevertheless, in determining the spatial rate of change in population density,thisstudyuseskabupatenasabasisofanalysissincethecapitalcityofeach kabupatenintheNCRisusedasacenterofdevelopmentinthekabupaten. 69 70 4.1. Urbanization in the NCR Similar to Indonesia's Central Bureau of Statistics (CBS), this study defines urbanization at the village level (see Section 2.1.1). However, the criteria used to classify rural and urban villages are difi‘erent fiom the CBS's. This section starts with describing the process of rural-urban classification followed by the analysis of the level of urbanization. In the latter analysis, rates of urbanization of urban villages and urban populations are presented and compared. Finally, this section presents results in the form of both temporal and spatial rate of change of the population densities. 4.1.1. Windy. Urbanization in Indonesia is defined at the desa or village level by categorizing the villages into rural villages and urban villages (Hamer et al., 1986; Firman, 1992). Number of urban population is defined as the population in the villages categorized as urban. This study uses the same method but a difl‘erent criterion to classify the rural and urban villages of the study area. Several criteria can be used to define urbanization and classify rural and urban areas. The first is the level of regional economic progress which is commonly approached by classifying the aggregate measures of the state of economic progress of the region (Williams et al., 1983). The second is land rent such as applied in the Schmid's (1968) and Thrall's (1987) study in land conversion fi'om rural to urban uses. The third is population density which is also a very common measure used to classify rural and urban areas (Goldberg and Chinloy, 1984; Firman, 1992; Sharbatoghlie, 1991; Hamer et al., 1986; 71 Sutton, 1989; Obudho and Waller, 1976). Finally, the combination of two or more criteria (Williams et al., 1983; CBS, 1988) Indonesia's Central Bureau of Statistics (1988) adopts the forth criteria. It classifies a village as an urban village if population density excwds 5,000 people/kmz, a less than and equal to 25 percent of agricultural households, and more than and equal to eight urban facilities” . Although the Central Bureau of Statistics uses multiple criteria, there are very strong critics in defining the criteria. According to Rietveld (1988), all of the criteria used to define urban village in Indonesia are very arbitrarily determined. Agricultural household, for example, is defined as the main job of the head of household while in the reality there is more than one working household member. The presence of an urban facility in the village is determined without considering its quality; and more importantly, there is a characteristic of the village which has no significance contribution in determining the degree of urbanization such as the existence of an elementary school in the village. In Java, the elementary school, especially the public elementary school, is present in each village since the Government through President Instruction has determined each village should at least have one elementary school. Firman (1992; p. 97) has criticized this approach by stating that ”these criteria are difiicult to apply because of inconsistency in result between them". Difl‘erent from Central Bureau of Statistics (1988) and Firman (1992), this study uses population density as a single criterion to classify rural and urban areas in the NCR. 2"Facilities cmsidered as urban facilities include prirmry school of equivalent, seemxiary school or equivalent, high school or equivalent, theater, hospital, maternity center, clinic, hardened or paved road, telephrme/post office, market with permmt building, showing center, bank, factory, restaurrnrt, public electricity, and party-equipment renting servrce. 72 Reasons to choose this single indicator are : (i) there are no comprehensive measures of economic progress available at the village level; (ii) there is no formal record nor comprehensive study about land rent in the NCR that can be used as a basis of the classification; (iii) population and total area data are well documented in the village level through lO-year national census so that population density for each village can be derived; and (iv) there is no complete record of census data of 1980 beyond the data of population and total area that can be accessed by this study in the Central Bureau of Statistics, Jakarta and in the Ofice of Statistics both in the kabupatens and in the province. Because of the forth reason, this study cannot use the Central Bureau of Statistics' criteria since the complete census data of 1990 cannot be compared with the incomplete census data of 1980. 4.1.2. MW! This study uses village's population density of 1,500 people/km2 as a cut off to difi‘erentiate between rural and urban villages in the NCR In other words, villages with population density of more than 1,500 people/1cm2 are classified as urban villages while those with less than or equal to 1,500 people/1cm2 are classified as rural villages. This study finds that the use of CBS's criterion of 5,000 people/km2 results in very small number of urban villages in the NCR. The analysis shows that from total of 1099 villages in the NCR there are only 18 villages that can be categorized as urban villages in 1980 which increased to 37 villages in 1990. This represents only 1.64 percent of all villages in 1980 and only 3.37 percent ofall villages in 1990. Table l and Figure 3 present 73 the comparisons of the number of villages categorized as rural and urban areas based on the village's population density of 5,000 people/km2 in 1980 and 1990. Table 1. Number of Villages in the Northern Coastal Region of West Java (NCR) by Population Density Interval in 1980 and 1990. Area Pop. Density Nu’mber of Villages Percent of Villages (people/m2) 1980 1990 1980 1990 R1 5 1,000 760 635 69.15 57.78 R2 1,001-2,000 246 55 22.38 5.00 R3 2,001-3,000 47 325 4.28 29.57 R4 3,001-4,000 18 19 1.64 1.73 R5 4,001-5,000 10 28 0.91 2.55 RURAL 5 5,000 1081 1062 98.36 96.63 U1 5,001-6,000 6 9 0.55 0.82 U2 6,001-7,000 5 5 0.46 0.46 U3 7,001-8,000 1 4 0.09 0.36 U4 8,001-9,000 2 6 0.18 0.55 U5 9,001-10,000 1 5 0.09 0.46 U6 2 10,000 3 8 0.27 0.72 URBAN > 5,000 18 37 1.64 3.37 NCR 1099 1099 100.00 100.00 SourcesofData:1980andl990PopdafionCensusesisswdbyCennalBurenuofStatistiesJakanaand theOfiicesofStafisficsofKahmatensBekasi,meang,Subang,andIndramyu. Nunberolwm “ a o o reflfagenumberabl vmagonrrm berso > ”'6 0'5 ' ' ' - m U4 U3 U2 U1 RS R4 33 R2 R1 Subregtone (U :Urben; R :Rurat) Figure 3. Distribution of the Villages in the NCR based on the Village's Population Density (Source : Table I) 74 The data (Table 1; Figure 3) show that the use of village's population density of 5,000 people/km2 as threshold to differentiate rural and urban areas contradicts with the assertion that the NCR is the most urbanized and industrialized region in Java (Soemarwoto, 1992; Firman, 1992; Hamer et al., 1986; Hill, 1992b) since the result of the analysis shows that there is only very small portion of the NCR that can be categorized as urban villages. Hamel er al. (1986; p. 14), for example, calculated that 21.00 percent of the urban population in West Java (1980) was mostly concentrated in the NCR (Firman, 1992). Since urban population in Indonesia is calculated based on urban villages, the high urban population must reflect the high number of urban villages. The result will be much lower if the other two CBS's criteria—agricultural households and urban facilities—are included in the analysis. Therefore, adoption of the CBS's criteria implies that there is a very low urbanization in the NCR and, comparatively, much lower in other regions in Java; and, it does not reflect the reality of urbanization in the NCR. In addition, Figure 3 shows that village's population density of 5,000 people/inn2 is not the best threshold to difl‘erentiate between rural and urban villages in the NCR since it does not depict a clear distinction of grouping between rural and urban villages. This study suggests a cutting point of 1,500 people/1cm2 to difl‘erentiate rural and urban villages. Using this level of population density, the level of urbanization and urbanization process in the NCR is better represented. The results of the analysis of the level of urbanization in the NCR are presented in the Tables 2 , Table 3, Figures 4, and Figure 5. 75 Table 2. Number of Rural and Urban Villages in the NCR in 1980 and 1990 (Classified based on the Village's Population Density of 1,500 people/km2 as a Cut Off to Differentiate Rural and Urban Village) Area Pop. Density Number of Villages Percent of Villages (people/kmz) 1980 1990 1980 1990 R1 _<_ 375 194 91 17.65 8.25 R2 376-750 368 317 33.48 28.84 R3 751-1125 247 321 22.47 29.21 R4 l,126-1,500 139 147 12.65 13.38 RURAL g 1,500 948 876 86.25 79.71 U1 1,501-1,875 48 69 4.37 6.28 U2 1,876-2,250 27 34 2.46 3.09 U3 2,251-2626 16 21 1.46 1.91 U4 _>_ 2,626 60 99 5.46 9.01 URBAN > 1,500 151 223 13.75 20.29 NCR 1099 1099 100.00 100.00 SourcesofData:1980and1990PoprdationCensusesissuedbyCenflalBrnemrofStafistichakaflaand the Offices of Statisties of Kabupaten Bekasi, Karawang, Subang, andlndramayu. Number of Village. N o o ’ “vying-nan} aorta. vmgenum boron UI R4 R3 Subreglona (151-4 2 Urban; R'l—4 : Rural) . Figure 4. Distribution of Rural and Urban Villages in the North Coastal Region of West Java in 1980 and 1990 Based on the Village's Population Density of 1,500 people/km2 as a Cut Ofl‘ to Difi‘erentiate Rural and Urban Villages (Source : Table 2) 76 Table 3. Changing Composition of Rural and Urban Population in the NCR in 1980 and 1990 Area Pop. Density Total Po lulation Percent of Population (people/kmz) 1980 1990 1980 1990 R1 5 375 443,004 300,792 9.65 4.78 R2 376-750 1,234,220 1,273,079 26.89 20.22 R3 751-1125 1,058,788 1,487,116 23.07 23.62 R4 1,126—1,500 674,900 795,385 14.70 12.63 RURAL 5 1,500 3,410,912 3,856,372 74.31 61.25 U1 1,501-1,875 285,916 410,672 6.23 6.52 U2 1,876-2,250 162,206 203,129 3.53 3.23 U3 2,251-2626 144,922 175,681 3. 16 2.79 U4 _>_ 2,626 586,318 1,650,514 12.77 26.21 URBAN > 1,500 1,179,362 2,439,996 25.69 38.75 NCR 4,590,274 6,296,368 100.00 100.00 Sources of Data : 1980 and 1990 Population Censuses issued by Central Bureau of Statistics, Jakarta and the Offices of Statistics of Kabupatens Bekasi, Karawang, Subang, and lndramayu. Total Population 1000000 1000000 1400000 1200000 1000000 800000 000000 400000 200000 parathion-90 population-'80 R4 R3 R2 R1 Sub-regions (U14 :Urhan; R1-4 :Raral) Figure 5. Total Population in Each Sub-region in the NCR for 1980 and 1990 (Source : Table 3) 77 The level of rural and urban villages in the NCR in 1980 and 1990 are summarized in Table 2 and Figure 4. Rural and urban areas are subdivided fiirther into four sub-regions (RI-4 and U1-4) based on the difl‘erence of the village's population density of 375 people/km? Sub-regions R1-4 to Ul-4 indicate the degree of urbanization fi'om the most rural area (R1) into the most urbanized area (U4). The level of rural and urban populations in 1980 and 1990 and the level of population in each sub—region of the rural and urban areas are summarized in Table 3 and Figure 5. Compared to Figure 3, Figure 4 shows village's population density of 1,500 people/km2 provides a clear difl‘erentiation between rural and urban villages in the NCR. This classification represents the best result among other alternatives that have been considered in this study. Table 2 shows that there are 151 urban villages (13.74 percent) in 1980 and increases to 223 urban villages (20.29 percent) in 1990. This means that average village urbanization rate in the NCR between 1980 and 1990 is 47.67 percent or 4.77 percent per year. Table 3 and Figure 5, on the other hand, show that urban population in the NCR increases from 1,179,362 people (25.69 percent) in 1980 to 2,439,996 people (38.75 percent) in 1990. The average urban population rate between 1980 and 1990 is 106.89 percent or 10.69 percent per year. This result shows that the level of urban population in the NCR at 25.69 percent in 1980 is higher than that of the level of urban population in West Java of 21.00 percent such as calculated by Hamer et al. (1986). This result is expected since the urbanization process in West Java is more concentrated in the NCR (Firman, 1992). 78 There are differences between urban village growth and urban population growth in the NCR between 1980 and 1990. In this period, urban population in the NCR increased by 10.69 percent per year while the urban villages increases by 4.77 percent per year. This implies that urban population grth in the NCR is determined not only by the increase of urban villages or changing status of the rural villages into the urban villages but also by other factors such as changing demographic factors, rural and urban development, industrialization, and other factors. According to Hamer et al. (1986; pp. iii and 1), ”this grth is the outcome of millions individual household and business decisions". The detailed factors affecting urbanization process in the NCR are described in Section 4.2. Table 2 also shows that the number of villages with a population density of less than or equal to 375 people/kin2 has decreased significantly fi'om 194 villages (17.65 percent) in 1980 to 91 villages (8.28 percent) in 1990, a decrease by 53.09 percent or 5.309 percent per year. This decrease also occurred in the sub-region with a population density of 376-750 people/km2 for which the number of villages has decreased fi'om 368 villages (33.48 percent) in 1980 to 317 villages (28.84 percent) in 1990. In these sub-regions the number ofthe villages has decreased by 13.86 percent between 1980 and 1990 or 1.386 percent per year. On the other hand, in the other sub-regions the number of the villages have increased between 0.576 and 6.500 percent per year in the period of 1980-1990. These figures show that the number of villages in the NCR with population density of more than 750 people/km2 have increased in the period of 1980-1990. Among these regions, the urban areas represents a higher increase as compared to rural areas. Among the urban areas, the most populous sub-region of urban area (U4) has the highest increase 79 at 65 percent over ten years or 6.50 percent per year in the period of 1980-1990. This implies that the highest urbanization rate occurs ill the region with highest population density, an indication of an agglomerative effect of urban population (Bhadra and Brandao, 1993). Table 3, on the other hand, shows that between 1980 and 1990 the proportion of rural population has decreased in all sub-regions of the rural area while the proportion of urban population has increased, especially in the urban hinge and in the most populous sub-regions of the urban areas. These figures also imply that an increase in urban population occurs mostly in the areas characterized by previously higher population density. “-3- MW The rate of change in population density can be used as an indicator of the concentration of population over time and space. In this study, the temporal rate of change in the population density (TRCPD) is considered as an indicator of the degree of urbanization process over a period of time since urban and rural areas are difl‘erentiated by population density. And, spatial rate of change in population density (SRCPD) indicates the spatial difl‘erences in the degree of urbanization fi'om capital city of kabupaten to the countryside. 41.3.1. W In this study, temporal rate of change in population density (TRCPD) is defined as the change of the NCR's population density over the period 1980-1990, and is expressed as 80 people/kmzlyear. It is calculated using equation 1, described in Section 3.3.2.1. The results of the analysis are presented in Table 4, Table 5, and Figure 6. Table 4 presents the means of rate of change in population density between 1980 and 1990 (TRCPD) in rural and urban areas as well as in each sub-regions in the NCR. These means are plotted in Figure 6 so that the patterns of TRCPD fi'om the most urbanized region (U4) to the most rural region (R1) can be easily seen. Table 5 presents the result of the analysis of variance (Anova) of the means of the TRCPD in the NCR It also presents the result of the analysis of mean comparison of the TRCPD in each sub—regions in the NCR using Least-significant Difi'erent (LSD) tests of the Multiple Range Tests. Both Table 4 and Figure 6 show that the TRCPD in the NCR is positive between 1980 and 1990. This indicates that population density increased throughout the region. However, the increase of population density is not evenly distributed between rural and urban areas and among the sub-regions in rural and urban areas. The TRCPD decreases from the most urbanized area (U4) to the most niral area (RI). The mean ofTRCPD of urban area is 115.5708 people/km2/year and that in rural area is 12.7631 people/ka/year. Statistically, the mean of TRCPD of urban area is very significantly difl‘erent from that of rural area with confidence level of 99 percent (a = 0.01). The yearly increase of the population density in the urban area is 9.01 times of that in rural area. Therefore, it can be interpreted that urbanization in the NCR during the period 1980-1990 increased mostly in areas with higher population densities. This substantiates the assertion by Henderson (197 7) that an the accumulation or movement of population in high density (core) regions occurs through a self-reinforcing process. 81 Table 4. Mean of Rate of Change in Population Density between 1980 and 1990 (TRCPD) in the North Coastal Region of West Java (NCR). Area Population Density Annual Rate of Change in Population (people/kmz) Density (people/kmz/year) R1 5 375 5.1043 R2 376-750 9.8172 R3 751-1125 14.5185 R4 1,126-1,500 20.0236 RURAL 5 1,500 12.7631 U1 1,501-l,875 19.4939 U2 1,876-2,250 36.5776 U3 2,251-2626 61.0957 U4 22,626 221.2178 URBAN > 1,500 115.5708 NCR 33.6240 SourcesofData: 1980 and 1990 PopulationCensuses issuedbyCentralBurmuofStatisties, Jakartaand the Offices of Statistics of Kahlpatens Bekasi, Karawang, Subang, and lndramayu. rtehange-popdens Sub-regions (U14 : Urban; R1-4: Rural) Figure 6. Mean of Rate of Change in Population Density between 1980 and 1990 in Each of Sub-regions of the NCR (Source : Table 4). The accelerated growth of population density over time is further substantiated by comparing the means of TRCPD among sub-regions in the NCR (Table 5). The analysis 82 shows that TRCPD is the highest in the most urbanized area (U4) at 221.2178 people/km2/year and lowest in the most rural area (R1) at 5.1043 people/ka/year (see also Table 4). Table 5. Mean Comparison of the Temporal Rate of Change in Population Density (TRCPD) among Sub-regions in the NCR using One Way Anova and Least- significant Different (LSD) Multiple Range Tests Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) Source D.F. Sum of Squares Mean Squares F-ratio F-prob. Among Sub-regions 7 391191667 558845.24 43.33 0.00 Within Region 1091 1407154023 12897.84 Total 1098 1799345690 Multiple Range Tests: LSD Tests with a (a = 0.01; b = 0.05; c = 0.10) Sub-regions R1 R2 R3 R4 U1 U2 U3 U4 R1 - R2 - R3 - R4 c c - U1 0 c - U2 c c c - U3 b b b b b c - U4 a a a a a a a - SourcesofData:1980andl990PopdadonCensuwsisamdbyC‘ennaleeauomefinichakanamd meOflicesomefisticsofKahipatenBekasLKamwangSubangandlndramayu. Further analysis using One Way Analysis of Variance (Anova) and Least-significant Different (LSD) Multiple Range Tests show that very significant differences exist in the means of TRCPD among sub-regions in the NCR (Table 5). Comparing rural and urban areas, it seems that the TRCPD's in rural areas are relative consistemly low compared to those in urban areas. In rural areas, only R4 with TRCPD of 20.0236 people/ka/year has a higher TRCPD than that of the R1 and of the R2 which have TRCPD of 5.1043 and 83 9.8172 people/km2/year, respectively (confidence level of 90 percent or or = 0.10). On the other hand, in urban areas, the U4 with TRCPD of 221 .2178 people/ka/year has very significantly higher TRCPD than that of the U1-3 and of the R1-4 (confidence level of 99 percent or or = 0.01). The sub—region U3 with TRCPD of 61 .0957 people/ka/year has a significantly higher TRCPD than that of U1 and R1-4 (or = 0.05) and also higher than that of the U2 (or = 0.10). The sub-region U2 with TRCPD of 36.5776 people/km2/year has higher 'I'RCPD than that of R1-3 (or = 0.10). Finally, sub-region U1 with a TRCPD of 19.4939 people/km2/year has a higher TRCPD than that of R1-2 (or = 0.10). The existence of the self-reinforcing process of population density growth implies that—assuming that spatial organization in the NCR is governed by spatial competition (Mabogunje, 1981; Mehretu, 1989)—peop1e in the region prefer living in urban areas with high population densities than in rural areas with low population densities. This may imply that there exists a preference to locate in urban areas due to the perception of a higher quality of life. This assertion will be visited again in the analysis of urbanization process in the NCR (Section 4.2). 4.1.3.2. Warm The spatial rate of change in population density (SRCPD) is defined as the spatial difl‘erences in the degree of population concentration over distance from the center of the region (Gould, 1972; Blair, 1991; Dicken and Lloyd, 1990; Rees, 1970). In this study, SRCPD indicates the spatial differences in the degree of urbanization process from capital city of kabupaten to the countryside. SRCPD is calculated by using a general decay function model, a simple negative exponential function described in Section 3 .3 .2.2. 84 This study assumes that the model—which is successfully applied in the developed countries (Haggett, Clifl', and Frey, 1977; Mehretu, 1989) to predict the decay of population density from the city center to the countryside—also applies in the NCR. Since there is no specific city in the NCR that can be referred as a center of the whole region of the NCR” , this study uses each capital city of the four kabupatens in the NCR as a city center. Consequently, the analysis of the SRCPD is conducted in each kabupaten in the NCR and the regional analysis of the SRCPD in the NCR is conducted by assigning average distance of the village to its capital city of kabupaten. This research addresses the value of b in each kabupaten and in the whole region. In predicting such parameters, the equation is transformed into a linear model. Using the Least Square Method or the Least Square Estimators (Neter and Wasserman, 1974; Johnston, 1991; Barber, 1988; Runyon and Haber, 1980; Ott, 1988), the value of b, In Do, and E can be determined by using equation 4, 5, and 6 described in the Section 3.3.2.2. The results of the analysis are presented in Table 6 and Figure 7. Table 6 presents the value of b, In Do, and E along with the statistical measures related to the linear model such as the strength of linear association (r, linear correlation), measure of goodness of fit of the regression model (r’, coefl'lcient of determination), significant testing of the strength of the variable relationships (Snedector's F-ratio). Figure 7 presents the result of the linear relationship between natural log of village's population density and the distance from the capital city of kabupaten. The figure plots only the positive value of the natural log of the village's population density by assigning numbers to the regression equations. ”ThereisnobigcityintheNCRalthmighthisregimislocatedbetweentwbofthebiggestcifiesmlndonesia, JakartaandCirebon However,fluencatleastfourunaflercifiesintheNCRwhichalsohappaiasthecapital citieeofthefourkabupntalsintheNCR. 85 Table 6. Rate of Change in Population Density (b) Over Distance (SRCPD) from the Capital City of Kabupaten Predicted using Linear Model with Least Square Method LinearModel : lan=1nDo -bX:E NCR Bekasi Karawang Subang Indrama b 0.044077 0.044255 0.048547 0.043955 0.041708 In Do 1.867912 1.815106 1.807865 1.904647 1.888894 r 0.872140 0.846900 0.892590 0.915010 0.861320 0.760620 0.717240 0.796720 0.837240 0.741870 Adjusted 72 0.760400 0.716040 0.796040 0.836580 0.741030 E 0.395100 0.482440 0.322270 0.286890 0.444110 F-statistic 3485.715 596.0956 1 175.795 1275.720 885.1787 LSig. level29 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.000 SourwsofData:1980and19901bpdafionCmmsesissuedbyCennaanreauomefistichakamand theOfficesofShfisticsofKahrpatenBekasi,Kamwang,Subangandmdramayu. Ln (population density, peopldka) 0.00 . . t . . . 4 . o 5 10 15 20 25 30 :15 40 Distance from Capital City of Kabupatcn (km) Figure 7. Distance Decay Function of the Population Density from the Capital City of Kabupatens of Bekasi, Karawang, Subang, and lndramayu, and in the NCR in 1990 (Source : Table 6). 2”Ii-test with significant level of or = 0.0000 means that the regression model is fitted with confidence level of more than 99 percent 86 All statistical measures used ill this analysis show that the model fits the situation in the region, including all kabupatens. The values of linear correlation (r) in all regions are very high with the values between 0.85 and 0.92, indicating a very strong predictive relationship between village's population density and the distance from the capital city of kabupaten. Furthermore, F-tests show that the relationships between village's population density and the distance from the capital city of kabupaten in all regions is very significantly strong with confidence level of more than 99 percent (see footnote 3). The values of the coefl'lcient of determination (12) are also very high in all regions with the values between 0.72 and 0.84. These indicate that the distance from the capital city of kabupaten explains 72 to 84 percent of the variance of the village's population density in the study area. However, the values of the expected result—b or the SRCPD—are very low in all regions with values of 0.0441, 0.0443, 0.0485, 0.0440, and 0.0417 for the NCR, Bekasi, Karawang, Subang, and lndramayu, respectively. This means that in Bekasi, for example, for each kilometer farther from the capital city of kabupaten the population density declines by 0.0443 people per square kilometer. This implies that there is no significant difl‘erentiation in the population density over distance from the capital city of kabupaten. Therefore, the rank size rule may not be the probable distribution of population in the NCR. In other words, such as found by Mehretu (1983) in his study of Cities of Sub- saharan Afiica, the simple negative exponential function, which has been very successful model for the developed countries, is not representative for the NCR. 87 Beyond the statistical reliability of the model, the actual value of the natural log of village's population density is plotted against its predicted value derived from the analysis (Figure 8). This plot shows whether the model is over or under estimate the actual value of the village's population density. +-+—-' Predicted value Mpopuletlon density). ppllka] LbbLo—Nunuouaoa Figure 8. The Relationship between the Actual Values of the natural Log of Village's Population Density and Its Predicted Values Derived from the Analysis. The 45°-line in the Figure 8 indicates a perfect model of prediction. If the model has a good prediction capability, the actual values of the natural log of the village's population density will be scattered around the line. In fact, in this study, the actual values of the natural log of the village's population density are concentrated below the line. It indicates that the model provides an over estimation of actual values and also indicates that the model does not represent the condition in the region. 88 4.2. The Urbanization Process in the NCR This section describes the urbanization process and its underlying causal factors in the NCR between 1982 and 1992. Instead of using census data for 1980 and 1990, the study uses the primary survey data for years of 1982 and 1992 to analyze the urbanization process in the region. The primary survey data cover a wide range of information related to rural and urban characteristics affecting urbanization. These data are not included in the census. 42.1. W The level of urban population is defined as the population in the urban areas consisting of the villages with population density of more than 1,500 people/km? The rate of change of the village's population density, consequently, indicates the process of urbanization and is used, in this study, as its indicator. Urbanization according to Hamer et a1. (1986) is determined by a complex set of individual household and business decisions. According to pull and push factor theory of tn'banization (Sovani, 1964; Choe 1981), regional factors afl‘ecting urbanization are grouped into ntral and urban factors. Rural factors are related to the agricultural and rural conditions which force population to migrate or ”concentrate” to urban areas. Urban factors are those urban conditions which draw people to migrate or ”concentrate” to urban areas. In the literature of urbanization (see Chapter II), rural factors are commonly referred to as push factors and urban factors are identified as pull factors. However, there is also other factor that cannot be categorized as one of the groups such as demographic factor which naturally occurs both in the rural and urban areas. 89 Since the time dimension is a critical variable in the urbanization process, the study investigated annual rates of change of all factors expected to affect urbanization, including push and pull factors. As in Section 4.1.3.1., the rate of change for all the factors in this analysis is calculated using equation 1 (Section 3.3.2.1.). According to pull and push theory (see Chapter II), urbanization is a firnction of push factors fiom agricultural rural area and pull factors of urban area. Therefore, the annual rate of change in regional population density is a function of the annual rate of change in the push factors, the annual rate of change in the pull factors, and the annual rate of change related to demographic factors. This relationship is investigated in this study using a linear multiple regression model (Section 3.3.2.3.) to identify specific causal factors affecting urbanization. The process uses stepwise multiple regression instead of simultaneously multiple regression to identify a multivariate equation with factors that represent critical causal of urbanization (Johnston, 1991). The factors that are expected to affect regional urbanization are summarized in Table 7. The rural push factors expected to afi‘ect urbanization (X;) are the regional changes in land tenure and the regional cimnges in the agricultural economy between 1982 and 1992. The regional changes in land tenure include the accelerated agricultural land parcelization, the increase in the absentee agricultural land ownership, and the increase in agricultural land conversion. The regional changes in agricultural economy include the 90 Table 7. List of Causal Factors Expected to Afi‘ect Regional Urbanization (The indicators and the identified variables [stated in their annual rate of change] were determined prior to conducting Linear Multiple Regression Analysis). Factors Indicators Identified Variables (Stated as Their Annual Rate of Cha_nge) Rural/Push W in Land Te_r_r_n_re: (X0 1. Agricultural land parcelization . X1, Households without dryland (%) (X1 -10) I . X2, HOIISChOI$ mm paddyland (%) k. x3. Households with < 0.5 ha dryland (%) Kl X4, Households with < 0.5 ha paddyland (%) . X5, Households with 0.5-1.0 ha dryland (%) f. X6, Households with 0.5-1.0 ha paddyland (%) g. X7, Households with >1 .0-2.0 ha dryland (%) Lh. x,, Households with >r.o-2.o ha paddyland (%) i. X9, Households with > 2 ha dryland (%) j. X10, Households with > 2 ha paddyland (%) L2. Absentee land ownership (Xl 1-12): .X“, land owned by absentee landlords (ha) F. X”, Number ofabsentec landlords per 1000 village population 3. Agricultural land conversion . X”, Agricultural land (%) (X1344) I F X14. WW (%) WW: “I. Agricultural labor wage rate (X15): Ia. X15, Agricultural labor wage rate during the Plowing Period (Rp.) 5. Agricultural land price (X16) : . X16, Average agricultural land price (Rpmillion) 6. Village employment structure . X17, Ayicultural labor (%) (xi-1-22) 3 - X18, TOW farmer (%) . X19, Sakap / sharecroppers (%) X20, Small scale enterprise (%) . X21, Small scale industry (%) . X22, Informal sector (%) Urban/Pull 1. Degree of Industrial development . Y1, Number of large scale industries (Y) in 1,000 village population (Y I .3) : . Y2, Number of medium scale industries . Y3, Number of small scale industries 2. Availability of public facilities a. Y., Number of clinics per 1,000 village population (Ya): .Ys, Number ofbanksper 1,000 village population . Y6, Number of public transportation (vehicles per 1000 village population) . Y7, Length ofpavedruads (km per 1,000 village population) 3. Availability of pre-college . Y3, Number of kindergarten erhrcational facilities per 1,000 . Yo, Number of elementary school villagepopulatioMYm): .Ym, Numberofsecondary school Y“, NW 011 h1g1! SChOOl Demographicl. Populationgrowth(Z,): ZhPopulationgrowthinthevillage (gt) 2. Migrgtion (Z2) : a. 24, Net migration in the village Una-moon} Rate of change in the village's Rate of change in the village's population density Prone-I (UP) population density (Um (UP) 91 decrease of real agricultural labor wage rate, the increase of agricultural land prices, and the changes in the structure of village employment. These factors combined likely affect urbanization due to migratory pressure on rural population's decreased economic opportunities in rural areas. The selected variables for agricultural land parcelization determined prior to linear multiple regression analysis are : 1. X1 : the annual rate of change in the percentage of household without agricultural dryland, 2. X2 : the annual rate of change in the percentage of household without paddyland, 3. X3 : the annual rate of change in the percentage of household with less than 0.5 ha agricultural dryland, 4. X4 : the annual rate of change in the percentage of household with less than 0.5 ha paddyland, 5. X5 : the annual rate of change in the percentage of household with 0.5-1.0 ha agricultural dryland, 6. X5 : the annual rate ofchange in the percentage ofhousehold with 0.5-1.0 ha paddy- land, 7. X1 : the annual rate of change in the percentage of household with more than 1020 ha agricultural dryland, 8. X3 : the annual rate of change in the percentage of household with more than 1.0-2.0 ha paddyland, 9. X9 : the annual rate of change in the percentage of household with more than 2.0 ha agricultural dryland, and 10. X10: the annual rate of change in the percentage of household with more than 2.0 ha paddyland. 92 Selected variables on absentee land ownership determined prior to linear multiple regression analysis are : 1 l. X": the annual rate of change in the percentage of land owned by absentee landlords, and . 12. X12: the armual rate of change in the number of absentee landlords per 1,000 village population. Selected variables on agricultural land conversion determined prior to linear multiple regression analysis are : 13. X13: the annual rate of change in the percentage of total agricultural land converted into non-agricultural uses, and 14. X“: the annual rate of change in the percentage of paddyland converted into non- agricultural uses. The variable on agricultural labor wage rate determined prior to linear multiple regression analysis is : 15. X15: the annual rate of change in the average agricultural labor wage rate during the plowing period (Rp./year). The variable on agricultural land prices determined prior to linear multiple regression analysis is : 16. X16: the annual rate of change in the average agricultural land prices (Rp. million/year). Selected variables on the structure of village employment determined prior to the linear multiple regression analysis are : l7. X17: the annual rate of change in the percentage of the agricultural labor, 18. X“: the annual rate of change in the percentage of the total farmer, 93 19. Xno: the annual rate of change in the percentage of the sharecroppers, 20. X20: the annual rate of change in the percentage of the population working in small scale enterprises, 21. X2; : the annual rate of change in the percentage of the population working in small scale industries, and 22. X22: the annual rate of change in the percentage of the population working in the informal sector. The pull factors of urban areas (Yj) expected to afi‘ect urbanization are the degree of industrial development, the availability of public facilities, and the availability of pre- college educational facilities. These were the three identified principal pull factors which would likely draw population towards urban areas to realize economic opportunities. Selected variables on the degree of industrial development determined prior to linear multiple regression analysis are : 1. Y; : the annual rate of change in the number of large scale industries per 1,000 village Population, 2. Y2 : the annual rate ofchange in the number ofmedium scale industries per 1,000 village population, and 3. Y3 : the annual rate of change in the number of small scale industries per 1,000 village population, Selected variables on the availability of public facilities determined prior to linear multiple regression analysis are : 4. Y4 : the annual rate of change in the number of clinics per 1,000 village's population, 5. Y5 : the annual rate of change in the number of bank per 1,000 village's population, 94 6. Y6 : the annual rate of change in the number of the public transportation (vehicles per 1,000 village population), and 7. Y7 : the annual rate of change in the length of the paved road (km per 1,000 village population). The selected variables on the availability of pre-college educational facilities determined prior to linear multiple regression analysis are : 8. Y3 : the annual rate of change in the number of kindergarten per 1,000 village poolllation. 9. Yo : the annual rate of change in the number of elementary school per 1,000 village population, 10. Ylo: the annual rate ofchange in the number ofsecondary school per 1,000 village population, and l 1. Y“: the annual rate of change in the number of high school per 1,000 village population, In addition, total village population increase, expected to affect urbanization, due to population growth and migration is identified. This increase cannot attributed to push factors nor pull factors. Therefore the factors afi‘ecting such an increase is treated separately md are, in this study, identified as demographic factors (Zk). The variable selected for population growth prior to linear multiple regression analysis is : 1. Z, : the village population growth. The variable selected for migration prior to linear multiple regression analysis is : 2. Z2 : the rate of change in the village net migration. 95 Therefore, the relationship between urbanization, defined as the rate of change in village population density, and factors that affect the process of urbanization (UP) can be statedas: 22 11 2 UP=f(ZXi,ZYj,ZZ/r) i=1 i=1 Fl Where : UP is the degree of regional urbanization 22 Z Xi are push factors i=1 11 Zl’j are pull factors Fl 2 22]: are demographic factors k=l This mathematical relationship is investigated using a linear multivariate model. Since multivariate regression is conducted using a stepwise method, final results will not include all identified variables. Final results are presented in the next section. 4.12. W Before presenting the results of the linear multiple regression analysis of urbanization process in the NCR, this section starts with presenting the magnitude of trends of all variables investigated. The summary of trends of all the variables is presented in Table 8. A positive sign of the mean rate of change of each variable represents the fact that the variable has increased annually during the period of 1982-1992. On the other hand, a negative sign of the mean rate of change represents that the magnitude of the variable has decreased annually during the same period. 96 Table 8. Trends of Causal Factors Expected to Afi‘ect Regional Urbanization. Positive and Negative Means of the Rate of Change for Each Variable Represents an Increase or Decrease during the Period of 1982-1992 Factors Indicators Identified Variables (Stated as Their Trend Annual Rate of Change) Rural/Push : (X1) 1. Agricultural land parcelization (X140) . X1, Households without dryland + . X2, Households without paddyland + . X3, Households with < 0.5 ha dryland - . X4, Households with < 0.5 ha paddyland - . X3, Households with 0.5-1.0 ha dryland - . X6, Households with 0.5-1.0 ha paddyland - . X1, Households with >1.0-2.0 ha dryland - . Xs, Households with >1 .0-2.0 ha paddyland - '. X9, Households with > 2 ha dryland - '. X10, Households With > 2 ha paddyland - .X11,landownedbyabaalteelandlords + . X12, Number ofabsentee landlords + . x13, Asricultmul land - .XlaPaddyland . 2. Absentee land ownership (X1 l-12): 3. Agricultural land conversion (X1344) I E. Agricultural labor wage rate (x51: .X15,Agricultm'allaborwagerate 5. Agricultural land prices (X15) : . X16, Average agricultural land prices + 6. Village employment structure (X1142) I X11, Agricultural labor + . X13, Farmer - . X19, Sakap/sharecroppas + . X20, Small scale enterprise + . X11, Small 80816 industry + . XE Informal sector + Urban/Pull 1. Degree of industrial development . Y1, Number of large scale industries + (Y1) (Ym) : . Y2, Number of medium scale industries + . Y3, Number of small scale industries + + 2. Availability of public facilities (Yul) : . Y4, Number of clinics + . Y5, Number of banks + . Y6, Number of public transportation + Y1, Length of paved roads + + 3. Availability of pie-college educational . Yo, Number of kindagarten + facilities (You) : . Yo, Number of elementary school + . Ylo, Number of secondary school Yll, Number oh high school . Demographic l.Populationgrowth(Zr): 21, Population growthinthevillage - (A) LMigation (24) : Net migra_tion in the villagg + Urbanhatloa Rate of change in the village’s population Rate of change in village's population density «1- Process (UP) density (UP) (UP) 97 Table 8 shows that regional push factors from the agricultural rural area for the period of 1982-1992 are characterized by the changes in land tenure and changes in the agricultural economy. Changes in land tenure are characterized by an increase in agricultural land parcelization or land disaggregation. Specifically, Table 8 shows that the percentage of landless households has increased while all categories of both agricultural drylands and paddylands have decreased. Moreover, it also shows that the hectarage of total agricultural lands as well as paddylands have decreased, indicating agricultural land conversion to other uses. These phenomena are reinforced by the facts that the number of absentee landowners and the hectarage of lands owned by the absentee landowners in the same period have increased in the NCR. For the same period, changes in the agricultural economy are characterized by a decrease in the real agricultural labor wage rates30 and an increase in the real value of agricultural land prices31 . Changes in the NCR's agricultural economy are also followed by changes in the structure of village employment. The percentage of population working as agricultural labors and the percentage of the sharecroppers have increased while the percentage of farmers (agricultural land owners) has decreased for the same period. Non-agricultural regional employment, on the other hand, has increased. This increase is characterized by an increase in the percentage of population working in small scale enterprises, in small scale industry, and in the informal sector. 1""l'hererrlrigriculttn'allrtborrtvngerateiscalculrltedbriaedontheaver'agevillage'swagerateintheplowingperiod andconva'tingthe l982valueinto 1992 valueusinginflatiourateof9percent. 3‘rhetigtieultutttlitiiitlptioeisottleultttotituitionotithetlweiugepiioeorltuuliuiliettample villagesandthcvalueof 1982iseonvertedintothevalueOt‘l992byusinginflationrateof9percent 98 Table 8 also shows that regional pull factors in the period of 1982-1992 are characterized by the increasing number of industries, public facilities, and pro-college educational facilities. The increasing number of regional industries is characterized by increases in the number of the large scale industries, medium scale industries, and small industries for every 1,000 village population. The increasing number of regional public facilities is characterized by increases in the number of clinics, bank, public transportation (vehicles), and length of the paved road (km) for every 1,000 village population. The increasing number of regional pre—college educational facilities is characterized by increases in the number of kindergartens, elementary schools, secondary schools, and high schools for every 1,000 village population. Regional population growth 1992 is lower than that in 1982 while regional net migration is higher in 1992 than that in 1982. The next question is to determine which of the factors have caused an increase in the rate of change in regional population densities. Specifically, which variables were the principal causal factors in determining regional urbanization during 1982-1992. To answer this question, all factors including push, pull, and demographic factors (see Table 7 and 8) were regressed with the change in the village's population density, as the dependent variable (Table 9). A multiple step-wise regression analysis was used and all assumptions and requirements of the model (see Section 3.3.2.3) were satisfied in this analysis. 99 Table 9. Causal Regional Urbanization Factors including T-tests Significant (Sig), Standardized Partial Regression Coefficient (ll-Coefficient), and Degree of Urbanization Process Explained by the Variance of Each Variable (Variance). Factors Indicators Variables (Stated as Their Sig. B Variance Annual Rate of Orange) (70} Rival/Push Wurst (28.16%) (45.40 %) 1. Agicultural land parcelization : X1, Households with zero dryland c 0.621 1.35 (7.16 %) sts, Households with < 0.5 ha dryland a 1.299 1.73 in, Households with 0. 5-10 ha paddyland c 0.454 1.31 on, Households with >1 .o-2.o ha paddyland - -0. 163 2.47 X10. Households with > 2 ha - -0. 101 0.30 2. Absentee land ownership: 9(11, Land owned by absaltee a 1.251 6.92 (8.62 %) landlords Din, Ntuuber of absentee landlords b 0.310 1.70 3. Agricultin'al land conversion : X13, Agricultural land a 1.550 9.03 ( 12.38 %) 2X14, Paddyland c 0.555 3.35 (17.24 %) 4. Agricultmallaborwagerate: x.,,Agticultuiallshoiwogetote c 0.173 2.12 (2.12%) 5. Agricultural landprices: Dru. Average agriculttnal landprices r .0273 4.97 (4.97 %) 6. Village employment structure : X11, Agricultural labor d 0.188 2. 55 (10.15 %) X“, Farmer a 0.654 5.37 X4234 Informal sector a 0.795 2. 23 Urban/Pull 1. Degree of industrial development Y1, Number of large scale industries - -0.147 7.43 (24.72 96) (7.43 %) 2. Availability of public facilities Y4, Number of clinics a -0.833 3.48 (11.09 %) Y5, Number of banks c 0.180 3.83 Ye, Number of pub. transp. vehicles d 0.229 2.00 Y1, Length of paved reads a 0.579 1.78 3. Availability of pie-college Y9, Number of elementary school a 0.842 4.48 educational facilities Yto, Number of secondary school e 0.202 1.72 (6.20 %) Demographic 1. Population growth : 21, Population growth in the village d -0.527 2.43 (6.72 '/o) (2.43 %) 2. Migration : Z2, Net migration in the village b -0.580 429 (4.29 %) Urbanization Rateofchangeinthevillage's Rateofchangein village's Process (UP) pow-lotion density WP) porllllllliOIl density (UP) (76. 84 %) Summary Statistics: Significance Level of T-test : Samplesize :44villages azlpercent d:15percent MultipleR :0.87656 b:5percent e220percent R-square :0.76835 c:10percent f:25percent Adj. R-square :0.50196 Sig. F-statistic: 0.0099 100 Since this regression analysis involves a lot of independent variables, one might suspect that multiple correlation (collinearity) among independent variables may exist. This study has, specifically, measured the collinearity using the tolerance of the variable and variance inflation factors (VIF). Results show that there is no multiple correlation existed among the independent variables included in the final equation. Factors determining urbanization in the NCR are presented in Table 9. Variables representing the push factors in the linear regression equation are households with zero dryland (X1), households with < 0.5 ha dryland (X3), households with 0.5-1.0 ha paddyland (X6), Households with > 1.0-2.0 ha of paddyland (X3), and households with > 2.0 ha of paddyland. These variables are used to indicate the degree of regional land parcelization. Both variables of the absentee land ownership are included in the equation, including land owned by the absentee landlords (X11) and number of absentee landlords (X12). Variables of agricultural land conversion (X13) and paddy land conversion (X14) are both included in the equation. Other push factors included in the equation are agricultural labor wage rate (X15), average agricultural land price (X16), agricultural labor (X17), farmers (X13), and informal sector (Xio). The pull factors included in the equation are number of large scale industries (Y1), number of clinics (Y4), number of banks (Y5), number of public transportation vehicles (Y5), length of the paved roads (Y7), number of elementary schools (Y9), and number of secondary schools (Yw). And, both variables of demographic factors, population grth (Z1) and net migration (22), are retained in the equation. 101 Therefore, the final of linear multiple regression equation expressing the factors affecting the urbanization process in the NCR can be stated as : UP=f(X1+X3+X6+Xs+Xlo+Xu+X12+X13+X14+X15+X16+ X” + X“ + X22 + Y1+ Y4+ Y, + Y6+ Y, + Y9+ Y“) + Zl-t-Zz) Table 9 also summarizes the partial regression coeficients. Since not all variables retained in the equation have the same measure, the partial regression coefficients are standardized using B-Coeflicient so that the strength of the efl‘ect among the factors can be compared. The last column of the Table 9 summarizes the percentage of variance of each factor that explain the variance of the urbanization process in the NCR In addition, the percentage value in the bracket of each indicator or each group of factor represents the total variance of each indicator or variance of each group of factor that accounts for the variance of the urbanization process in the NCR. The results indicates that the linear multiple equation provides a good explanatory model of regional urbanization process since the value of the multiple correlation coeficient (R), the index of the strength of relationship between UP and all factors, is very high (0.87656). In addition, the linkage efl‘ects between UP and all factors in the equation is statistically very significant (or = 0.0099) with confidence of more than 99 percent. Combined the push, pull, and demographic factors explain 76. 84 percent of the variance in the urbanization process in the NCR. In other words, the causal factors account for 76.84 percent of the regional urbanization. From this 76.84 percent, push factors contribute 45.40 percent or 59.08 percent of the explained variance. The pull factors and demographic factors, on the other hand, contribute 24.72 percent or 32.17 percent of the 102 explained variance and 6.72 percent or 8.75 percent of the explained variance. This implies that urbanization in the NCR is determined by both push and pull factors but the push factors have stronger effect on the regional urbanization. The strength of push factors is almost twice (1.84 times) as that of the pull factors. A more detailed discussion of each variable (push, pull, and demographic factors) associated with the regional urbanization is provided in the following sections. 4.2.2.1. [ugh Fggtgrs Push factors accounts for 45.40 percent of the equation's explained variance of 76.84 percent. It means that 59.08 percent of the explained urbanization process in the NCR is determined by agricultural rural factors. Push factors can be grouped further into changes in land tenure and changes in the agricultural economy of the NCR. 4.2.11.1.Wm The changes land tenure explain 28.16 percent of the urbanization process in the NCR This means that changing land tenure contributes 62.03 percent of the push factors in urbanization. The total contribution of the changes in land tenure is determined by three groups of factors, namely : the increase in agricultural land parcelization, the increase in absentee land ownership, and the increase in agricultural land conversion into non-agricultural uses. ' The increase of the agricultural land parcelization contributes 7.16 percent of the explained urbanization. This explanation is 25.43 percent of the changing land tenure or equal to 15.77 percent of the total push factors of the urbanization. There are five 103 variables used to explain the contribution of the increase of agricultural land parcelization in explaining urbanization process in the NCR. Those variables are households with zero dryland (X1), households with < 0.5 ha dryland (X3), households with 0.5-1.0 ha paddyland (X6), households with >1 .0-2.0 ha paddyland (X3), and households with > 2.0 ha paddyland (X10). Among these variables, a decrease in the percentage of households with < 0.5 ha dryland (X3) appears to afi‘ect urbanization very significantly with confidence level of 99 percent (or = 0.01), and contributes 1.73 percent of the explained urbanization or 24.16 percent of the total agricultural land parcelization. An increase in the percentage of landless households (X1) and a decrease in the percentage of households with 0.5-1.0 ha paddyland (X6) also affect urbanization at confidence level of 90 percent (a = 0.10) by contributing 1.35 percent and 1.31 percent variance in the urbanization or 18.85 percent and 18.30 percent of the total agricultural land parcelization. The increase of the absentee land ownership contributes 8.62 percent to regional urbanization. This explanation reflects 30.61 percent of changes in land tenure or 18.99 percent of the total push factor in the urbanization. Two variables are used to explain the contribution in the increase of absentee land ownership associated with regional urbanization, including the increased hectarage of the land owned by the absentee landlords (X11) and the increased number of absentee landlords (X12). ' The increased hectarage of the land owned by the absentee landlords is highly correlated with regional urbanization (confidence level 99 percent or or = 0.01) by contributing 6.92 percent of total variance, or 80.28 percent of the absentee land ownership, or 24.57 percent of changes in land tenure. The increased number of absentee landlords also significantly 104 determines urbanization process (confidence level 95 percent or a = 0.05) contributing 19.72 percent to absentee land ownership or 6.04 percent to changes in land tenure. The most important efi‘ect on urbanization in the NCR results from the changes in land temrre (and also from push factors) is mostly determined by the increase in the conversion of agricultural land. This increase contributes 12.38 percent to regional urbanization. This explains 43.96 percent of the changes in land tenure or 27.27 percent of the total push factors associated with urbanization. Two variables are used to explain the contribution of the agricultural land conversion to urbanization, including the decreased hectarage of the total agricultural land (X13) and the decreased hectarage of the total paddy land (X14). The decreased hectarage of total agricultural land affects regional urbanization very significantly (99 percent confidence level or a = 0.01), contributing 9.03 percent of the explained urbanization, 72.94 percent of the agricultural land conversion, or 32.07 percent of the changes in land tenure. The decreased hectarage of paddy land also affects regional urbanization (90 percent confidence level or a = 0.10) by contributing 3.35 percent ofthe explained variance urbanization, 27.06 percent ofthe agricultural land conversion, or 11.90 percent of the changes in land tenure. 4-2-2-1-2- Wm: Changes in the agricultural economy explain 17.24 percent of the regional urbanization variance. This is equal to 37.97 percent of the push factors associated with the urbanization. The total contribution of changes in the agricultural economy is determined by three groups of factors such as the decrease of real agricultural labor wage 105 rates, the increase in agricultural land prices, and changes in the village's structure of employment. Decreased agricultural labor wage rates, represented by the variable of real agricultural wage rate (X15), affects regional urbanization at 80 percent confidence level (or = 0.20), contributing 2.12 percent to urbanization variance. This accounts for 12.30 percent of the changes in the agricultural economy or 4.67 of the total push factors. Increased agricultural land prices, represented by the variable of average agricultural land prices (X15), affect regional urbanization at 75 percent confidence level (a = 0.25), contributing 4.97 percent to the regional urbanization. This accounts for 28.83 percent of changes in the agricultural economy or 10.95 percent of the total push factors. Changes in the structure of village employment explain 10.15 percent of the regional urbanization. This accounts for 58.87 percent of changes in the agricultural economy or 22.36 percent of the push factors. Three variables are used to represent changes in the structure of village employment in explaining urbanization. These variables are the increase in the percentage of agricultural labor (X17), the decrease in the percentage of number of farmer (X13), and the increase in the percentage of the population engaged in employment in the informal sector (X22). The increased percentage of agricultural labor explains 2. 55 percent of the urbanization and accounts for 25.12 percent of changes in the structure of village employment or 5.62 percent of changes in the agricultural economy (80 percent of confidence level or or = 0.20). The decreased percentage of the number of farmers afi‘ects tu'banization very significantly (99 percent confidence level or a = 0.10), explaining 5.37 106 percent of the variance in urbanization, 52.91 percent of changes in the structure of village employment, or for 31.15 percent of changes in the agricultural economy. Finally, the increased percentage of informal sector also significantly affects the urbanization (90 percent confidence level or a = 0.10) and explains 2.23 percent of urbanization, or 21.97 percent of changes in the structure of village employment, or 12.94 percent of changes in the agricultural economy. 4333- Missing Pull factors explain 24.72 percent of regional urbanization. This is equal to 32.17 percent of the regression's explained total variance of 76.84 percent. In other words, pull factors account for 32. 17 percent of the known urbanization factors identified in the NCR which is less than the contribution of push factors of 45.49 percent. Pull factors can be grouped into the degree of industrial development, changes in the availability of public facilities, and changes in the availability of pre-college educational facilities. The contributions of each group described in the following sections. 4-22-2-1- WW Other than expected, the degree of industrial development does not afi‘ects regional urbanization. From the three variables identified prior to analysis (see Table 7 and Table 8), only one variable is retained in the linear multiple regression equation-the number of large scale industries for every 1,000 village population (Y1). Although this variable accounts for 7.43 percent of the explained variance in regional urbanization, statistically this factor is not significance (confidence level only at 47 percent or or = 0.53). 107 4.2.2.2.2. Chgngas in the Avgfl' hill}! of Pgblig Fggilitias Changes in the availability of public facilities explain 11.09 percent of the regional urbanization or 44. 86 percent of the pull factors. Four variables represent changes in the availability of public facilities after completion of the linear multiple regression analysis. These variables are the increase in the number of clinics for every 1,000 village population (Y 4), the increase in the number of banks for every 1,000 village population (Y 5), the increase in the number of public transportation vehicles for every 1,000 village population (Y 5), and the increased length of the paved roads for every 1,000 village population (Y7). The increased number of clinics for every 1,000 village population very significantly appear to affect urbanization very significantly with confidence level of 99 percent (a = 0.01) and explains 3.48 percent of the urbanization, 31.38 percent of changes in the availability of public facilities, or 14.08 percent of the pull factors. The increased number of banks for every 1,000 village population explains 3 .83 percent of the urbanization and appears not very significant (confidence level 80 percent or a = 0.20). It accounts for 34.54 percent of changes in the availability of public facilities or 15.49 percent of the total pull factors. The increased number of public transportation vehicle for every 1,000 village population appears afl‘ects regional urbanization (confidence level 85 percent or a = 0.15). It explains 2.00 percent of urbanization, 18.03 percent of changes in the availability of public facilities, or 8.09 percent of the total pull factors. The increased length of the paved roads for every 1,000 village population very significantly affects urbanization (confidence level 99 percent or a = 0.01). It explains 1.78 percent of the urbanization 108 process or accounts for 16.05 percent of the development of public facilities or accounts for 7.20 percent of the pull factors which explain the process. 4.2.2.2.3. thnges in 1h; Ang' 9111;: 91' P1332113; Mggtigng Fggilitig Changes in the availability of pre-college educational facilities explain 6.20 percent of regional urbanization, accounts for 8.07 percent of the known urbanization process and represents 25.08 percent of the total pull factors associated with urbanization. Two variables which represent changes in the availability of pre-college educational facilities are retained alter the regression analysis. These variables are the increased number of elementary schools for every 1,000 village population (Y9) and the increased number of secondary schools for every 1,000 village population (Yio). The increased mrmber of elementary schools for every 1,000 village population appears to affect regional urbanization very significantly (confidence level 99 percent or or = 0.01). It explains 4.48 percent of urbanization, 72.26 percent of changes in the availability of pre-college educational facilities, or 18.12 percent of the total pull factors. On the other hand, the increased number of secondary schools for every 1,000 village population appears to be of limited importance in urbanization (confidence level 80 percent or a = 0.20). It contributes 1.72 percent to urbanization, 27.74 percent of changes in the availability of pre-college educational facilities, or 6.96 percent of the total pull factors. 109 4.2.2.3. gemggranhg' Factggs Demographic factors contribute only 6.72 percent or 8.7 5 percent of the explained urbanization in the region. Surprisingly, population growth (Z1) appears to be of limited significance in urbanization (confidence level 85 percent or or = 0.15) and explains only 2.43 percent of urbanization or 36.16 percent of the demographic factors. On the other hand, the increase of net migration in the region significantly afi‘ects urbanization (confidence level 95 percent or or = 0.05) and contributes 4.29 percent to urbanization. This contribution accounts for 63.84 percent of the demographic factors. 413- WM This section describes the efi‘ect of the village proximity to the center of development or to the central city on regional urbanization. Specifically, it describes whether the village proximity to the city significantly affects the urbanization and to which extend proximity a factor in explaining urbanization. Cities considered as the centers of development in this study include : (i) Jakarta, the capital city of Indonesia located on the west side of the NCR; (ii) Cirebon, the city developed by the Government of West Java to balance the development of Jakarta, located on the east side of the NCR; and (iii) the capital city of each kabupaten in the NCR (see Figure 2). Therefore, the location of the village relative to Jakarta, Cirebon, and capital city of kabupaten, respectively, are analyzed and described. The proximity of the village to city is measured by its distance (kilometer, km) to the city and defined as : l 10 l. The village is classified as close to Jakarta if the distance of the village to Jakarta is 5 150 km and the village is classified as far from Jakarta if the distance of the village to Jakarta is > 150 km. 2. The village is classified as close to Cirebon if the distance of the village to Cirebon is 5 150 km and the village is classified far from Cirebon if the distance of the village to Cirebon is > 150 km. 3. The village is classified as close to the capital city of kabupaten if the distance of the village to the capital city of kabupaten is _<_ 20 km and the village is classified as far from the capital city of kabupaten if the distance of the village to the capital city of kabupaten is > 20 km. In the analysis, the proximity of the village to the city is treated as a dummy variable. Such a dummy variable is introduced into a multiple regression equation presented in Table 9 (previous section). The dummy variable can be set in the regression model by defining the variable as : D, is 1 ifthevillageisclosetoJakarta,0ifnot; or D; is 1 ifthe village is close to Cirebon, 0 ifnot; or D3 is 1 if the village is close to the capital city of kabupaten, 0 if not. Suppose that the linear multiple regression equation presented in Table 9 is denoted asUP thentheefi‘ectofthevillageproximitytoJakartaonurbarrizationcanbestatedas UP, = UP + D]. Similarly, proximity efi'ect of the village to Cirebon is stated as UP; = UP + D2 and proximity effect of the village to the capital city of kabupaten is defined as UP3 = UP + D3. This analysis follows Johnston (1991) who believes that the 111 use of dummy variable in this type of analysis is more advantageous than the use of conventional analysis of variance. He states that, "Dummy variables can be used as an alternative analysis of variance procedure, with the added advantage over the conventional method that the partial regression coefficients can be used, where relevant, to test whether each group mean is significantly different fiom the mean represented by the constant. More importantly, they can also be used in combination with continues variables, those measured on interval or ratio scales [while dummy variables are measured on nominal scale]. This allows both conventional regression methods and analysis of variance of the residuals to be performed in a single procedure” (Johnston, 1991; pp. 113-114). The results of the analysis are summarized in Table 10. The first column of the table is a statistical summary of the regression equation which has been presented in Table 9 (UP). The next columns (UP1- UP3) represent statistical summaries of the regression analysis afier the distance factor (D,- D3) is introduced into UP. Table 10. Statistical Summary of the Multiple Regressions of Urbanization with Distance Factors in the NCR Expressed as without (UP) and with (UPH) Dummy Variables and Their Significance (F -significance)', the Explained Variance of the Village Proximity to Jakarta (UP,), to Cirebon (UP;), and to the Capital City of Kabupaten (UP3); and Its Significance in Afl‘ecting the Urbanization Process (Di-significance) Statistical UP UP, UP; UP3 Summary (as Table 9) (UP + D,) (UP + D2) (UP + D3) Multiple R 0.87656 0.88427 0.87800 0.88371 Multiple R-square 0.76835 0.78194 0.77088 0.78094 Adjusted R—square 0.50196 0.50649 0.48147 0.50424 F—significance 0.0099 0.0118 0.0165 0.0121 Standard Error 25.2067 25.2067 25.8379 25.2643 Di-significance 0.2902 0.6521 0.3091 Explained Variance 1.36 % 0.25 % 1.26 % 112 Table 10 shows that by introducing the dummy variable of the village proximity to Jakarta (DI) the explained variance of the urbanization process in the NCR increases from 0.76835 to 0.78194. It means that the village proximity to Jakarta explains 1.36 percent of the urbanization process. This explanation is statistically insignificant due to the fact that D, is only significant at the level of or = 0.2902. However, considering that Jakarta is the most developed city in Indonesia and has been recognized as the city of migrants, proximity of villages to Jakarta can be considered as having an efi'ect on regional urbanization if, and only if, the type I error)2 is allowed at or = 0.30 (or confidence level of 70 percent). Table 10 also shows that even when the type I error at confidence level of 70 percent ( ct = 0.30), proximity of villages to Cirebon and to the capital city of kabupaten are not statistically significance in afi‘ecting regional urbanization. Proximity of villages to Cirebon is only statistically significance at a = 0.6521 (confidence level of 34 percent) and explains only a very small percentage (0.25 percent) of the urbanization process. Similarly, proximity of villages to the capital city of kabupaten is only statistically significance at a = 0.3091 (confidence level of 69 percent) and explains 1.26 percent of urbanization. Further analysis pursued in this section and presented below, aims to determine whether proximity of the urban villages to the cities significantly affects regional 3’"Atypelerr'orinastatisticrrltestoflrypotherrisiscornmitterlwhenadecisionismadetorejectanullhypotlresis whichisactuallytr'ue. Theprobabilityofcornmittingatypelerrorisa(alpha)' (Barber, 1988', p. 265). 113 urbanization. In other words, it analyzes whether the distance of the village-city of the urban area of the region significantly affect urbanization. As before, dummy variables are introduced to represent urban villages of the NCR (D.) (defined in Section 4.1.1.) into the regression equation presented in Table 9. Suppose the urbanization process in the urban areas is denoted as UP. and is defined as UP. = UP + D.. The efiects of proximity of the villages to Jakarta, Cirebon, and the capital city of kabupaten (DI-D3), then, can be assessed by introducing DI-D3 into UP.. Therefore, UPs, UP5, and UP. represent linear multiple regression equations incorporating the effect of proximity to the cities in urbanization process in the urban areas. The results of the analysis are summarized in Table 11. Table 11. Statistical Summary of the Multiple Regressions of the Urbanization Process in the NCR with Dummy Variables of Urban Area and Urban Area with the Village Proximity to Jakarta, to Cirebon, and to the Capital City of Kabupaten Statistical UP. UP, UP, UP. Summary (UP + D.) (UP+D.+D,) (UP+D.+D2) (UP+D.+D.) Multiple R 0.90117 0.90998 0.90306 0.91041 Multiple R-square 0.81211 0.82806 081551 0.83542 Adjusted R-square 0.57478 .058925 055928 0.60684 F-Significance 0.0041 0.0043 0.0070 0.0032 Standard Error 23.3980 22.9965 23.8206 22.4983 Di-significance 0.0490 0.2127 0.5717 0.1217 Explained Variance 4.38 °/. 4.13 °/. 4.72 °/. 6.71 % Table 11 shows that the dummy variable of urban area (D.) significantly afi'ects urbanization in the NCR (confidence level of 95 percent or a = 0.0490). In other words, the acceleration of the urbanization process in the NCR is higher in urban area than that in rural area, indicating, again the self-reinforcing nature as described in Section 4.1.3.1. This also shows that proximity of urban villages to Jakarta afi'ects the urbanization process 1 14 with confidence level of 78 percent (or = 0.2127) and is higher than the effect of the village proximity to Jakarta for the whole region (confidence level of 70 percent or a = 0.2902) (see Table 10). This indicates that village distance to Jakarta only influences urban areas. Proximity of urban villages to Cirebon does not significantly affect regional urbanization since it is only significance at a = 0.5717, indicating that Cirebon does not influence the whole region of the NCR (Table 10) neither the urban area of the NCR (Table 11). On the other hand, the proximity of the urban villages to the capital city of kabupaten appears to have Significant efl‘ect on urbanization ( confidence level of 87 percent or or = 0.1217). V. URBANIZATION AND AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT The relationship between urbanization and agricultural development in the NCR presented in Section 2.2. is summarized below (Figure 9). This relationship is affected by both national and regional development policies, namely maintaining the region as the bread basket of the nation and the adoption of a hierarchical regional development strategy (see also Section 1.2.1). Urbanization and agricultural development are two processes which affect each other by direct or indirect linkages, including through urbanization with its underlying causal factors. The increased regional urbanization affects agriculture by putting additional pressure on the agricultural resource base and, at the same time, the increased demand for food in urban areas forces the agricultural sector to increase productivity with a reducing resource base. An increase in agricultural economic activity, on the other hand, stimulates urbanization by inducing regional industrial development through the redistribution of labor among rural and urban sectors (see Section 1.2.2). On the contrary, a government policies undermining a viable agricultural sector forces people to seek better economic opportunities in urban areas. Urbanization, in turn, is influenced by push factors fiom rural agricultural areas, pull factors of urban areas, and demographic factors. In other words, agricultural development also afl‘ects regional urbanization. Moreover, each of the push factors also affects the regional urbanization (see Sections 2.2.1.2.; 2.2.3; 3.3.2.3; and 4.2.). For example, regional urbanization is very significantly affected by increased agricultural land 115 116 288328 ago—=65 as dean 336 a Sewage: 985. 835 noon—6a.... 5 Sam GEES: emmmmm? my: $5235.»: ensuing—zest e ZO—hauN—Zetmy—D e mflOhU1 - 2 HA 5.2080 3.1732 2.0348 "*‘l' > 2 HA 2.1645 0.7380 1.4266 "*"”" Paddyland : 0 HA 43.4802 53.4057 -9.9255 ""* < 0.5 HA 27.4689 27.0698 0.3991 0.5 - 1 HA 16.4220 12.0536 4.3684 **"* >1 - 2 HA 9.2136 5.7011 3.5125 "1'" > 2HA 3.5350 1.6350 1.9000 "1'" Source : Primary Data (Village Survey) Significance Level : t 20 m tit 10 M iii"!!! 1 ml tfi 15 W 0". 5 W The increase of regional landless households is not significantly associated with the decrease of the percentage of households with < 0.5 ha dryland or < 0.5 ha paddyland. Although households with < 0.5 ha dryland and households with < 0.5 ha have decreased fiom 32.31 percent in 1982 to 30.86 percent in 1992 and from 27.47 percent in 1982 to 27.07 percent in 1992, respectively, this decrease is not significantly difl'erent. This indicates that the percentage of subsistence farmers in the region remain largely the same during the period. Regional agricultural development has, therefore, been unable to reduce the percentage of subsistence farmers. 121 However, the increase of regional landless households is associated very significantly with the decreases in the percentage of households with _>_ 0.5 ha dryland and that with 3 0.5 ha paddy land during the period of analysis (confidence level of 99 percent or or = 0.01). Households with 0.5-1.0 ha dryland and those with 0.5-1.0 ha paddyland have decreased very significantly between 1982 and 1992 from 12.15 percent to 8.57 percent and from 16.42 percent to 12.05 percent, respectively. These decreases are the greatest among other land divisions. For the same period, households with >1 020 ha dryland and those with >1 .0-2.0 ha paddyland have decreased very significantly fiom 5.21 percent to 3.17 percent and fiom 9.21 percent to 5.70 percent. The decrease ofthe percentage of household with this hectarage of paddyland is greater than those of dryland (39.16 percent and 38.11 percent, respectively). Finally, the percentage of households with > 2.0 ha dryland decreased less than that of paddyland. Households with > 2.0 ha dryland decreased by 65.74 percent fi'om 2.16 percent in 1982 to 0.74 percent in 1992. Similarly, the households with > 2.0 ha paddyland decreased by 53.67 percent from 3.54 percent to 1.64 percent. 5.2.2. . , Changes of the agricultural land ownership distribution in rural areas of the NCR during the 1982-1992 period are of the same magnitude as those ofin the NCR as a whole. Landless households increased and the households with agricultural landholdings decreased. No significant changes exist in the percentage of households with < 0.5 ha agricultural lands and those with < 0.5 ha of paddyland in the period of 1982-1992. 122 Results of the analysis of changes in the distribution of the agricultural land ownership in the rural areas are summarized in Table 13. Table 13. Difi‘erences in the Distribution of Household Land Ownership in the Rural Areas of the NCR between 1982 and 1992 Type and Percent of Households with Land Mean of Paired Significant Size of Land Difl‘erences Difl‘erences 1982 1992 Dryland : 0 HA 49.9700 58.4400 -8.4700 "”* < 0.5 HA 28.5488 27.6554 0.8933 0.5 - 1 HA 12.1075 8.5271 3.5804 *"" >1 - 2 HA 6.3692 4.3267 2.0425 "” > 2 HA 2.5496 1.0708 1.4787 "*“ Paddyland : 0 HA 47.4821 55.9400 -8.4879 *"” < 0.5 HA 26.9838 25.4217 1.5621 0.5 - 1 HA 13.6300 10.9513 2.6788 "" >1 - 2 HA 9.4188 5.7129 3.7058 "* > 2 HA 3.4096 1.7192 1.6904 "*" Source : Primary Data (Village Survey) Significance Level : 10 percent “‘"* 1 percent 5 percent ‘ 20 percent ”‘ .. 15 m i... It shows that the percentage households without agricultural drylands and paddylands increased very significantly in the period of 1982-1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or or = 0.01), an increase from 49.97 percent to 58.44 percent and from 47.48 percent to 55.94 percent, respectively. This means that the percentage of households without dryland increased by 16.95 percent and that without paddyland increased by 17.82 percent. Households with < 0.5 ha agricultural dryland and those with < 0.5 ha paddyland decreased insignificantly during the period. 123 Households with 0.5-1.0 ha agricultural dryland decreased very Significantly fi'om 12.11 percent in 1982 to 8.53 percent in 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or o. = 0.01), a decrease of 29.56 percent. Households with >1 .0-2.0 ha agricultural dryland decreased significantly from 6.37 percent in 1982 to 4.33 percent in 1992 (confidence level of 95 percent or or = 0.05), a decrease of 32.03 percent. Also, the percentage of households with > 2.0 ha dryland decreased very significantly from 2.55 percent in 1982 to 1.07 percent in 1992 (confidence level of99 percent or a = 0.01), a decrease of 58.04 percent. On the other hand, the percentage of households with 0.5-1.0 ha paddyland decreased very significantly by 19.66 percent, a decrease fi'om 13.63 percent in 1982 to 10.95 percent in 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or or = 0.01). The percentage of households with >l.0-2.0 ha paddyland decreased significantly by 39.38 percent, a decrease from 9.42 percent in 1982 to 5.71 percent in 1992 (confidence level of 95 percent or a = 0.05). The percentage of households with > 2.0 ha dryland increased very significantly by 49.56 percent, decreases fi'om 3.41 percent in 1982 to 1.72 percent in 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). The analysis shows a very significant increase in agricultural land parcelization during the period of 1982-1992, characterized by an increasing landless households. Agricultural land parcelization puts agricultural development at risk since it threatens the welfare of the population engaged in agriculture due to diseconomies of scale of agricultural enterprise (Toner, 1979; Dunford, 1981); and Lockeretz, 1986). Moreover, the combined efi'ects of increased absentee land ownership (described in Section 5.3) and increased agricultural 124 land conversion (described in Section 5.4) in rural areas undermines the role of the region as the bread basket of Indonesia. This effect may be mitigated through future consolidation of agricultural lands. 5.3. Absentee Land Ownership in Rural Areas and the NCR Region Regional urbanization is commonly accompanied by increased prices of agricultural lands. Due to a knowledge of regional land use plans, land speculators can acquire agricultural lands proposed for urban development. This increases the hectarage of land in rural areas owned by the people from outside rural areas. In the NCR, the increased hectarage of land owned by the outsiders, however, is not merely determined by the increased land speculation but also determined by other factors such as increased investment in agricultural land as a hedge against inflation. In the sociological terms, the Sland owned by the outsiders is usually referred to as absentee land and controlled by absentee land owners or commonly called as absentee landlords. In the NCIL the parallel terms are commonly used such as ”tanah gontai" and "tuna tanah" (or ”spekulan” to indicate land speculators). This section describes the changes in the degree of absentee land ownership in the rural areas and the region as a whole during the period of 1982-1992, including changes in the hectarage of absentee lands and the number of absentee landlords. However, this study does not difi‘erentiate between the absentee lands caused by land speculation or other investments in agricultural lands by urban inhabitants. The method used to assess changes in absentee land ownership is identical to that used in distributional changes in land ownership. 125 5.3.1. Awntee mg OwngLship in ghg NCR Rggiog This section describes the changes in absentee land ownership in the NCR between 1982 and 1992. Results of the analysis are summarized in Table 14 in which absentee ownership of dryland, paddyland, and total land are presented. Table 14. Regional Differences in the Hectarage of Absentee Lands and the Total Number of Absentee Land Owners or Absentee Landlords between 1982 and 1992 Lands Owned by and the Total in the Village Mean of Significant Number of Absentee Landlords Paired Differences in the Village 1982 1992 Difi‘erences ha ha ha Total Absentee Land : l. Dryland 12.4530 87.8927 -75.4398 """ 2. Paddyland 34.0455 48.4470 -14.4016 *“" 3. Dryland and Paddyland 46.4985 136.3397 -89.8412 ***" no. no. no. Total Absentee Landlords with: 1. Dryland 3.3409 11.0000 -7.6591 "*" 2. Paddyland 25.0909 29.7273 -4.6364 *** 3. Dryland and Paddyland 28.4318 40.7273 -12.2955 *""”" Source : Primary Data (Village Survey) Significance Level : a 20 percent «a 10 m eases 1 mm " 15 percent "" 5 percent The total absentee lands and the number of absentee landlords in the region increased very Significantly between 1982 and 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). Average absentee lands in the region, which was assessed at the village level, increased by 89.84 ha, an increase from 46.50 ha in 1982 to 136.34 ha in 1992. It means that total absentee lands in the NCR increased by 193.20 percent during the period of 1982-1992 or 19.32 percent annually. Average mrrnber of absentee landlords, on the other hand, increased by 12.30, an increase from 28.43 in 1982 to 40.73 in 1992. Therefore, the 126 average number of absentee landlords increases by 43.26 percent or 4.33 percent annually. The total hectarage of absentee lands increased faster than the number of absentee landlords, indicating more concentrated absentee land ownership. Comparing the total hectarage of absentee lands of dryland and paddyland, it shows that increased absentee hectarage can be attributed to an increase in absentee dryland. Average absentee dryland in the region increased very significantly by 75.44 ha, an increase from 12.45 ha in 1982 to 87.89 ha in 1992 (confidence level of99 percent or a = 0.01). This means that the total absentee dryland in the NCR increased by 605.94 percent during the period of 1982-1992 or 60.59 percent annually. Average absentee paddyland, meanwhile, increased very significantly by 14.40 ha, an increase from 34.05 ha in 1982 to 48.45 ha in 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). This means that the total absentee paddyland in the NCR increased by 42.29 percent during the period of 1982- 1992 or 4.23 percent annually. This pattern of increase in absentee dryland is accompanied by a higher number of absentee landlords acquiring dryland than those acquiring paddyland. Average number of absentee landlords with dryland increased by 229.34 percent within period of 1982-1992 or 22.93 percent annually, an increase fi'om 28.43 in 1982 to 40.73 in 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a. = 0.01). Meanwhile, the average number of absentee landlords with paddyland increased only 18.49 percent or 1.85 percent annually, an increase from 25.09 in 1982 to 29.73 in 1992 (confidence level of 90 percent or a = 0.10). While it is more economical to invest in paddyland than that in dryland, the high increase of absentee dryland in the NCR might be attributed to the increased land 127 Speculation in the region because the land speculators usually have on-hand information regarding rural lands allocated for urban uses which is rarely an irrigated land (see Section 1.2.1.). This is especially important given existing the Government of Indonesia's policies prohibiting conversion of paddyland to non-agricultural uses. 5.3.2. A n 11 hi ' h A Changes in absentee land ownership in the rural areas of the NCR during the period are more staggering than those in the region as a whole. Absentee land ownership in the rural areas for the period of 1982-1992 is summarized in Table 15. It shows that the degree of absentee land ownership in the rural area is much greater than that in the whole region of the NCR Table 14 and 15 show that in 1982 the average hectarage of absentee lands and number of absentee landlords at the regional level were 46.50 ha and 28.43, respectively. This is smaller than that in the rural areas which are 67.88 ha and 40.38, respectively. In 1992, the figures of the NCR are 136.34 ha and 40.73 which are also less than those of rural areas with 198.86 ha and 54.42, respectively. Changes in land ownership in rural areas, however, is similar to that in the region. Table 15 shows that total absentee lands and the number of absentee landlords in rural areas increased very significantly between 1982 and 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or or = 0.01). 128 Table 15. The Differences in the Absentee Land Ownership and the Number of Absentee Land Owners (Absentee Landlords) in the Rural Areas of the NCR between 1982 and 1992 Lands Owned by and the Total in the Village Mean of Significant Number of Absentee Landlords Paired Difl‘erences in the Village 1982 1992 Differences ha ha ha Total Absentee Land : 1. Dryland 18.2138 134.4054 -116.192 "" 2. Paddyland 49.6667 64.4563 ~14.7896 ""* 3. Dryland and Paddyland 67.8805 198.8617 -130.9812 "*** no. no. no. Total Absentee Landlords with: 1. Dryland 2.2083 12.3750 -10.l667 ""5 2. Paddyland 38.1667 42.0417 -3.8750 3. Dryland and Paddyland 40.3750 54.4167 -14.0417 "*" Source : Primary Data (Village Survey) Significance Level : t 20 percent 5" 10 percent “m“ 1 percent " 15 percent *”’“ 5 percent Average absentee land increases from 67.88 ha ill 1982 to 198.86 ha in 1992, an increase of 130.98 ha. This means that total absentee lands in the ma] areas increased by 192.96 percent during the period of 1982-1992 or 19.30 percent annually. Average number of absentee landlords in rural area, meanwhile, increased from 40.38 in 1982 to 54.42 in 1992, an increase of 14.04. Therefore, the number of absentee landlords increased by 34.77 percent in the period of 1982-1992 or 3.48 percent annually. Similar to the comparison at regional level, the increase in absentee land is larger than the increase in the number of absentee landlords, indicating that absentee landlords is becoming more concentrated. Comparing the total hectarage of absentee lands (dryland and paddyland), Table 15 shows that the increase in absentee land in the rural areas can be more attributed to the 129 increased in absentee dryland. Average absentee dryland increased significantly by 116.192 ha, an increase from 18.21 ha in 1982 to 116.192 ha in 1992 (confidence level of 95 percent or a = 0.05). This means that absentee dryland in rural areas increased by 638.06 percent during the period of 1982-1992 or 63.81 percent annually. Absentee paddyland, meanwhile, increased very significantly fi'om 49.67 ha in 1982 to 64.46 ha in 1992 (confidence level of99 percent or or = 0.01), an increase of 14.79 ha. This means that absentee paddyland in rural areas increased by 29.78 percent during the period of 1982-1992 or 2.98 percent annually. Increases in absentee dryland is accompanied by a higher number of absentee landlords acquiring dryland rather than paddyland. The average number of absentee landlords with dryland increased very significantly by 460.18 percent within period of 1982-1992 or 46.02 percent annually, an increase from 28.43 in 1982 to 40.73 in 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). However, the average number absentee landlords with paddyland increase insignificantly, indicating that the absentee paddyland in nrral areas is also becoming more concentrated in absentee ownership. 5.4. Agricultural Land Conversion in Rural Areas and the NCR Region According to Schmid (1968) and Firman (1992), regional urbanization is accompanied by the increased demand for land to support residential and industrial estates. Since urban land is limited, the agricultural lands are commonly put under pressures for conversion to non-agricultural uses to keep up with urbanization. Therefore, it is expected that agricultural lands in the NCR are under pressure of conversion to non- agricultural uses. 130 This study assesses the changes of total agricultural lands in the rural areas and in the region as a whole between 1982 and 1992. The main focus of this assessment is to see whether irrigated lands are mostly converted to non-agricultural uses. This addresses the concern to preserve the region's importance as the bread basket of Indonesia. The following sections describe the results of the analysis of agricultural land conversion in rural areas and in the region as a whole. The method used to assess land use change between 1982 and 1992 are the same as in the previous chapters. 5.4.1. WWW Results of the analysis of changes in the total agricultural land between 1982 and 1992 in the NCR region are summarized in Table 16. It includes the magnitude of irrigated land and agricultural dryland conversions both in total hectarage and weighted hectarage by number of the village population. This shows that the average irrigated land decreased significantly with confidence level of 99 percent (a = 0.01) and that the average agricultural dryland decreased Significantly with confidence level of 85 percent (a = 0.15), indicating that agricultural land conversion afi‘ects mostly irrigated land, the pillar of agricultural productivity of the region. Average irrigated land hectarage decreased by 73.18 ha (25.62 percent) in the period of 1982-1992 or 2.56 percent annually, a decrease from 285.69 ha in 1982 to 212.52 ha in 1992. This decrease is also very significant when the total hectarage of irrigated land is weighted by the number of village population. 131 Table 16. Differences in the Total Land (ha) and Total Land for Each 1,000 Village Population (ha/1,000 village population) for both Irrigated Land and Agricultural Dryland in the NCR between 1982 and 1992 Type of Agricultural Land Total in the Village Mean of Significant Converted Paired Differences into Non-agricultural Uses 1982 1992 Differences ha ha Irrigated Land : 1. Total Hectarage 285.6945 212.5166 73.1778 ***** 2. Total Hectarage for Each 58.2595 34.1545 24.1050 **"'" 1,000 Village Population ha ha Agricultural Dryland : 1. Total Hectarage 67.3977 49.1259 18.2718 ‘1‘ 2. Total Hectarage for Each 14.7352 8.0759 6.6593 *" 1,000 Village Population Source : Primary Data (Village Survey) Significance Level : s 20 m sea 10 W ass-11a 1 percent it 15 m I... 5 mm The average agricultural dryland, on the other hand, decreased by 18.27 ha or 27.11 percent in the period of 1982-1992 or 2.71 percent annually (confidence level of 85 percent or significant at a = 0.15), a decrease from 67.40 ha in 1982 to 49.13 ha in 1992. The confidence level of the loss of agricultural dryland is higher (confidence level of 90 percent or a = 0.10) ifthe hectarage ofagricultural dryland is weighted by the number of village population. 132 541- MW Changes in the total agricultural land between 1982 and 1992 in rural area of the region are sunnnarized below (Table 17). Table 17. The Differences in the Total Land (ha) and Total Land for Each 1,000 Village Population (ha/1,000 village population) for both Irrigated Land and Agricultural Dryland in the Rural Areas of the NCR between 1982 and 1992 Type of Agricultural Land Total in the Village Mean of Significant Converted Paired Differences into Non-agricultural Uses 1982 1992 Differences ha ha Irrigated Land : 1. Total Hectarage 382.3441 286.5920 95.7521 "*" 2. Total Hectarage for Each 80.9563 47.1675 33.7888 ""* 1,000 Village Population ha ha Agricultural Dryland : 1. Total Hectarage 78.3896 55.9579 22.4317 2. Total Hectarage for Each 19.71 13 9.9446 9.7667 ** 1,000 Village Population Source : Primary Data (Village Survey) Significance Level : a 20 W ass 10 W cease 1 mm In 15 percent ms 5 percent Irrigated land and agricultural dryland conversions are summarized in total hectarage and weighted by the village population. In rural areas, the village's average irrigated land decreased very significantly (confidence level of 99 percent or or = 0.01) while the average agricultural dryland decreased insignificantly. This indicates that agricultural land conversion includes mostly irrigated land. This represents an average decrease by 25.04 percent or 2.50 percent annually, a decrease from 382.34 ha in 1982 to 286.59 ha in 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). This decrease is also very significant when the total hectarage of irrigated land is weighted by the number of village population 133 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). The average agricultural dryland conversion is, on the other hand, insignificant. Weighted by number of village population, this decrease is, however, significant (confidence level of 85 percent or a = 0.15). It is clear that land conversion analysis in rural areas and in the region as a whole show that irrigated land has been mostly sacrificed in the process of urbanization. This process undermines the future sustainability of the regional agriculture especially in maintaining its contribution to the national food self-suficiency. 5.5. Irnpacts of Agricultural Land Conversion on Household Income At the regional level, the increased irrigated land conversion is risking the NCR capability to maintain its key role as the bread basket of Indonesia. At the household level, it is not always true that those who are involved in irrigated land conversion will have diminished welfare. This study assessed the impacts of irrigated land conversion on the welfare of the households involved in irrigated land conversion. Using data from the Project of Land Conversion in Java, Center for Agro Economic Research (PAE), this study compared the welfare of the farming households before and alter irrigated land conversion. The data represent on-farin, off-farm, and total income of 52 households involved in irrigated land conversion in the NCR over the last ten years (see Section 3.1.2. ). In this study, the household welfare is measured by total household income per year. The household income value before land conversion is converted into the 1992 value, the year after the land conversion household income is measured, using an inflation rate of 9.0 percent per year. With the standardized value of income, the level of income before and alter land 134 conversion can be compared using t-tests for paired-samples method such as discussed in Section 3.3.2.5. Results of the analysis are summarized in Table 18. It includes average households income on-farm, oE-farm, and total income before and after land conversion. Table 18. Difi'erences in On-farm, Ofilfarm, and Total Incomes (Rupiah, Rp.) of Farming Households Before and Alter Irrigated Land Conversion during the Period of 1982-1992. Sources 011 Mean of Household Income Mean of Paired Significant Income (Rp./Y ear) Differences Difference Before Land Conversion After Land Conversion fight-farm 1,576,587.62 2,102,767.88 -526,l80.26 "" -farm 1,460,608.96 2,075,777.40 -615,168.44 ""* Total 3,037,196.58 4,178,545.29 -1,141,348.71 "*" Source: HmsehddvaeyConmaedbymerjeaongriadmrdIandComemionmJavameCenmr for Agro Economic Research (PAE), 1993. Significance Level : * 20 percent ”" 10 percent "m" 1 percent 5‘ 15 percent "" 5 percent Table 18 shows that total household income afier land conversion is very significantly higher than that before land conversion (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). Income increases fiom Rp. 3,037,196.58 to Rp. 4,178,545.29, an increase of Rp. 1,141,348.71 or 37,58 percent. This indicates that the welfare of the households increased due to the conversion of irrigated land. Comparing total income with on-farm and ofllfarm income, Table 18 also shows that on-farm and off-fann household incomes afier land conversion are significantly higher than those before land conversion. It is expected that the ofl-farm income is higher after land conversion. 135 Surprisingly, the result of the analysis also Shows that the on-farm income is higher after the households conducting land conversion. This is unlikely true unless the households involved in land conversion acquire more agricultural land after land conversion. Further analysis conducted in this study verifies the suspicion. In fact, average household irrigated land significantly increases from 1.0665 ha per household before land conversion to 1.2628 ha per household after land conversion, an increase of 0.1962 ha per households (confidence level of 95 percent or a = 0.05). This indicates that the households uses the return from land conversion to further invest in other irrigated lands, resulting in higher hectarage of irrigated land. An additional question pursued in this study is whether the household's decision to convert land economically rational. If it is, then, it may be expected that regional land conversion is primarily dictated by market prices and that government policy does not significantly affect household decisions regarding land conversion. The decision is an econonrically rational one if on-farm incomes of the households not involved in land conversion is insignificantly difi‘erent from the after land-conversion on-farm income of those involved in land conversion. For the purpose of this analysis, on-farm income after land conversion of those households involved in land convern'on is compared with on-farm income of households not involved in land conversion using the t-test for two independent samples (see Section 3.3.2.5). The samples of the households not involved in land conversion is also based on the data provided by the Project of Land Conversion in Java (see Section 3.1.2. for detail). The result of the analysis is presented in Table 19. 136 Table 19. Difli‘ences between A fter-Iand-Conversion-On—farm Income of the Households Involved in Land Conversion and On-farm Income of Those not Involved in Land Conversion, 1992 Mean of Household Income Mean of Significant (Rp./Year) Differences Difference After Land Conversion No Land Conversion lOn-farm 2,102,767.88 1,564,273.75 53 8,494. 13 Source : Household Survey Conducted by the Project of Agricultural land Conversion in Java, the Center for Agro Economic Research (PAE), 1993. Significance Level : ‘ 20 percent “" 10 percent ”"" 1 percent “ 15 percent "" 5 percent It shows that no significant difference exist in the means of the on-farm income of those not involved in land conversion and the after land-conversion on-farln income of those involve in land conversion. This indicates that farm households in the NCR will convert their land if it is economically profitable; otherwise, they will not. This implies also that the government will not be able to restrict agricultural land conversion in the NCR unless the govermnent promotes indirect policy measures in the agricultural and nrral sectors which enhance farm household incomes and profitability of agricultural enterprises. 5.6. Structural Changes in Regional and Rural Village Employment Modernization theory of urbanization asserts that urbanization is accompanied by regional structural change in employment. In other words, regional urbanization is accompanied by a decrease of percentage of population working in agricultural-related activities and increases in the percentages of people employed in industrial and service- related activities. 137 This section describes structural changes of regional and rural employment in the NCR assessed at the village level during the period of 1982-1992. The primary focus of the analysis is to determine if the percentage of people employed the agricultural sector in the region during the last ten years has decreased; and, whether the trend also occurs in the nrral areas. The analysis uses a paired t-test similar to the previous in Section 3.3.2.5. The results of the analysis are summarized below (Table 20). Table 20. Differences in the Regional and Rural Area's Employment Structure between 1982 and 1992 Percent of Population Mean of Significant Types of Employment Paired Differences 1982 1992 Differences In E NCR : Agricultural Labor 22.4864 22.2720 0.2143 Farmer (operator) 24.0291 12.2289 11.8002 ""* Sharecroppers (sakap) 20.1564 14.7836 5.3727 ”"* Manufacturing Labor 1 1.9532 22.4200 -10.4668 "*" Small Scale Enterprise 7.5334 11.0880 -3.5545 "*" Government Oficial 4.4484 6.1586 -1.7102 "*“ Private Enterprise 4.0159 5.7039 -1.6880 "*" Others 5.3780 5.3452 0.0327 Inthe Rm MofmgNCR: Agricultural Labor 28.5929 34.8946 -6.3017 " Farmer (operator) 31.1454 17.9908 13.1546 ""* Sharecroppers (sakap) 26.1000 22.9992 3.1008 Manufacturing Labor 2.5258 6.2729 -3.7471 ""* Small Scale Enterprise 7.1371 11.8246 -4.6875 "" Government Oflicial 1.7463 3.1683 -1.4221 *”* Private Enterprise 0.7646 1.2521 -0.4875 *"""" Others 1.9883 1.5996 0.3887 Source : Primary Data (Village Survey) Significance Level : “ 20 percent “W 10 percent "*" 1 percent 0* 15 mt *tlt 5 mm 138 Regional and rural structural changes in employment during the period of 1982-1992 are identified. Since the analysis is conducted at the village level, the types of employment described in this study are somewhat difi‘erent from those usually used in the analysis of regional structural change of employment in the regional economic literature. Village employment, in this study, is classified on the basic of the largest share (more than 50 %) of employment contributing to total individual income. Eight types of employment are identified : 1. Agricultural labor, percentage of the village population engaged in agriculture by providing labor input to farm enterprises. 2. Farmers, percentage of the village population engaged in agriculture by operating their own agricultural enterprises. 3. Sakap/sharecroppers, percentage of the village p0pulation engaged in agriculture through either land leases or sharecropping. 4. Manufacturing labor, percentage of village population supplying labor input to manufacturing sector. 5. Small scale enterprises, percentage of the village population engaged in subsistence,‘ small scale trade without labor inputs outside the household. 6. Government officials, percentage of the village population employed in the public sector. 7. Private enterprises, percentage of the village population employed in the local business sector using outside labor input. 8. Others, percentage of the village population engaged in other activities. 139 At the regional level, Table 20 shows that village employment in 1982 is composed of 22.49 % agricultural labor, 24.03 % farmer, 20.16 % sharecropper, 11.95 % manufacturing labor, 7.53 % small scale enterprise, 4.45 % government oficial, 4.02 % private enterprise, and 5.38 °/o others. This employment structure is very significantly different from 1992, in which, the village employment was composed of 22.27 % agricultural labor, 12.23 °/o farmer, 14.78 °/o sharecropper, 22.42 °/o manufacturing labor, 11.09 % small scale enterprise, 6.16 % government omcial, 5.70 % private enterprise, and 5.35 % others. Although there is no significant change in the percentage of agricultural labor, the percentages of farmer and sharecropper have decreased very significantly in the region during the period 1982-1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). The percentage of self-employed farmers decreased by 49.11 percent from 24.03 percent in 1982 to 12.23 percent in 1992. The percentage of sharecroppers decreased by 26.67 percent from 20.16 percent in 1982 to 14.78 percent in 1992. Employment in the manufacturing, small scale enterprises, the government sector, and the private enterprise sector, meanwhile, grew very significantly in the region during 1982- 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). Employment in the manufacturing sector increased by 87.62 percent from 11.95 percent in 1982 to 22.42 percent in 1992. Small scale enterprise employment increased fiom 7.53 percent in 1982 to 11.09 percent in 1992, a growth of 47.28 percent. Employment in the government sector increased by 38.43 percent, an increase from 4.45 percent in 1982 to 6.16 percent in 1992. Finally, 140 private enterprise employment increased from 4.02 percent in 1982 to 5.70 percent in 1992, a growth of 41 .79 percent. These figures show that at the aggregate regional level of the NCR, a decrease of employment in the agricultural sector is accompanied by a high increase of employment in the manufacturing sector. In other words, the regional structural change of employment is characterized by a decrease of employment in the agricultural sector and shift of employment to the manufacturing sector. It means that urbanization in the NCR is accompanied by a structural change of employment such as asserted in modern urbanization theory. On the other hand, the structural change of employment in the nrral areas of the NCR is of a different magnitude than that of the region as a whole. In rural areas, village employment in 1982 is composed of 28.59 % agricultural labor, 31.15 % farmer, 26.10 % sharecropper, 2.53 °/o manufacturing labor, 7.14 °/o small scale enterprise, 1.75 % government sector, 0.76 % private enterprise, and 1.99 % others. This structure is significantly difi'erenr fiom that in 1992, during which, village employment was composed of 34.89 % agricultural labor, 17.99 % farmer, 23.00 % sharecropper, 6.27 % manufacturing labor, 11.82 % small scale enterprise, 3.17 % govemment sector, 1.25 % private enterprises, and 1.60 % others. Different fi'om the regional aggregate, it shows a significant increase in the percentage of agricultural labor in the nrral areas from 28.59 percent to 34.89 percent, an increase of 22.04 percent (confidence level of 80 percent or a = 0.20). The percentage of farmer decreased very significantly by 42.25 percent fiom 31.15 percent in 1982 to 17.99 percent 141 in 1992 (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). No significant decrease is apparent in the percentage of sharecroppers during the same period. Employment in manufacturing and private enterprises in rural areas grew very significantly during this period (confidence level of 99 percent or or = 0.01). Meanwhile, employment in small scale enterprises and the government sector grew significantly (confidence level of 95 percent or or = 0.05). Manufacturing employment increased by 147.73 percent from 2.53 percent in 1982 to 6.27 percent in 1992. Small scale enterprise employment increased from 7.14 percent in 1982 to 11.82 percent in 1992, a growth of 65.55 percent. Government employment increased by 81.14 percent from 1.75 percent in 1982 to 3.17 percent in 1992. Finally, the private enterprise employment increased from 0.76 percent in 1982 to 1.25 percent in 1992, a growth of 64.47 percent. Five fundamental difi'erences between nrral and regional structural changes of employment exist. First, to the period, rural employment is still dominated by agricultural employment. Second, the percentage of agricultural labor in rural areas increases significantly at 22.04 percent. This increase is much higher than that in the region at only 0.95 percent. Third, although employment in the manufacturing sector in nrral areas increased very significantly, the increase is higher than that in the region at 147.73 percent and 87.62 percent, respectively, but its absolute value is much less than that of the region. Forth,theincreaseofsmallscaleenterpriseishigherinruralareasthanthatintheregion at 65.55 percent and 47.28 percent, respectively. Finally, the employment ratio in private enterprisesintheruralareasismuchlessthanthatintheregionasawhole. 142 These figures imply that at the regional level : (i) a decrease of the employment in the agricultural related activities is followed by a significant increase in the employment in the manufacturing industries and small scale enterprises; and (ii) a decrease in the percentage of self—employed farmer is not followed by an increase in employment in the agricultural sector, an indication that manufacturing industries and small scale enterprises have the capacity to absorb farmers displaced from the agricultural sector. Meanwhile, for rural areas the figures imply that : (i) a decrease of the employment in the agricultural sector is not followed by a significant increase in the employment in the manufacturing sectors; and (ii) a decrease in the percentage of self-employed farmers is followed by an increase in employment in agricultural laborer and small scale enterprises, an indication that displaced farmers in rural areas are either being employed as future agricultural laborers or entering the labor force of small scale enterprises. VI. REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT OF THE NORTHERN COASTAL REGION OF WEST JAVA (NCR) 6.1. Regional Development of the NCR Regional development of the NCR cannot be separated from regional development of Jakarta-West Java as a whole, in which West Java has been designated as the hinterland of Jakarta (see Section 1.2.1. and Section 2.2.3.). In this regional development framework, sectoral development, especially industrial development, which is "deemed saturated” in Jakarta is to be developed in West Java (Hamer et al., 1986). This indicates that development in the region favors areas with better infi'astructure and proximity to the seat of government. Since the NCR has a better infrastructure and proximity to Jakarta, the industrial development in West Java is more concentrated in this region (Hill, 1992b). This study confirms Hill's assertion that the government policy to subsidize medium and large-scale industries (see Section 1.2.1) results in a higher degree of industrialization in the region. Instead of calculating the value added, this study assesses the increased number of industries during the period of 1982-1992. The increased number of industries indicates a higher degree of industrialization in the NCR Table 21 summarizes the result of mean comparison in the number of industries between 1982 and 1992. In this analysis, the industry is categorized as : (i) large scale industry, i.e. an industry with more than or equal to 100 employees; (ii) medium scale industry, i.e. an industry with more than or equal to 20 but less than 100 employees; and (iii) small scale industry, i.e. an industry with more than or equal to 5 but less than 20 employees. Changes in the degrees of regional industrialization are assessed at the village level using the method presented in Section 3.3.2.5. 143 144 Table 21. Differences in Regional Industrialization between 1982 and 1992 Number of Industries in the Mean of Significant Types of Industry Villag: Paired Differences 1982 1992 %-Change Difi‘erences In the NCR : Large scale industry (LSI) 0.0909 4.4091 4750.50 -4.3182 ””* Medium scale industry (MSI) 0.7273 2.6136 259.36 -1 .8864 *" Small scale industry (SSI) 6.0909 11.0455 81.34 -4.9545 "" LSI /1,000 village population 0.0177 0.7709 4255.37 -0.7S32 "*“ MSI/l,000 village population 0.1343 0.4052 201.71 -0.2709 *" SS1/1,000 village population 0.9514 2.1286 123.74 -1 . 1773 "" Source : Primary Data (Village Survey) Significance Level : e 20 W on 10 W on“ 1 page,“ “ 15 percent “" 5 percent Table 21 shows that the village's average number of large scale industries increased very significantly from 0.0909 in 1982 to 4.4091 in 1992, an increase of 4.3182 or 4750.50 percent during the period or 475.05 percent annually (confidence level of 99 percent or a = 0.01). The figure also increased very significantly after the number of large scale industries is weighted by the village population. The village's average number of medium scale industries increased significantly from 0.7273 in 1982 to 2.6136 in 1992, an increase of 1.8864 or 259.36 percent during the period or 25.94 percent annually (confidence level 01‘ 90 percent or a = 0.10). The level of significant of the increased number of medium scale industries is the same afier it is weighted by village population. This study also finds that the small scale industries in the NCR increased very significantly during this period, namely an increase fi'om 6.0909 in 1982 to 11.0455 in 1992, an increase of 4.9545 or 81.34 percent during the period or 8.13 percent annually. 145 In correspondence with the regional development of Jakarta-West Java which resulted in the increased number of industries of all scales, the NCR region is also affected the regional development of West Java. The regional development master plan of West Java was developed in 1974 (Government of West Java, 1990) and is updated every five years along with the five-year plan for national development. According to this master plan, regional development in West Java adopts a functional integration rather than a territorial integration as its strategy of regional planning with " growth centers" as the principal instrument of its spatial policy (see Section 1.2.1). In this study, a growth center is defined as "induced urbanization through a combination of direct public investments and capital subsidies to private enterprise" (Friedman and Weaver, 1979, p.6). Functional integration, meanwhile, is formed on the basis of mutual self-interests among regions. Given inequalities at the start, a functional integration is always hierarchical with accumulating power at the top. On the other hand, the territorial integration is derived fiom common bonds of social order forged by history within a given place. Although they will also be characterized by inequalities of power, territorial relationships are tempered by mutual rights and obligations which the members of a territorial group claim from each other (Friedman and Weaver, 1979; Friednrarr, 1988). Such a regional development strategy is biased towards the advantage of urban development (Friedman, 1988) and characterized by large investment in the urban- industrial sector (Rondinelli, 1985). There are two important problems associated with urbanization driven by such a regional development strategy (see Chapter IV). First, I46 agricultural development will be negatively affected by urbanization (see Chapter V). Second, rural areas would take part in the general process of growth diffusion only to the extent that they were subject to the impact of the urban economy (Friedman and Weaver, 1979). In other words, the urbanization process is not associated with social urbanization and increasing opportunities for development in rural areas (Mehretu, 1989). Therefore, it can be expected that there are rural-urban disparities in the distribution of the development benefits as a result of a cumulative causation process (Myrdal, 1957) or self reinforcing process (see Section 4.1.3.1.) The previous chapter described changes in several aspects of agricultural development along with regional urbanization of the NCR. The following section describes the extent of nrral-urban disparities in the distribution of some benefits of economic progress, distribution of marketing facilities, and the availability of educational and health care facilities. 6.2. Rural-Urban Disparities Rural-urban disparities, in this study, are defined as an uneven distribution of goods, resources, incomes, and services between rural and urban areas of the NCR (Matthews, 1983). This study does not assume that nrral-urban disparities in the region are created by lack of resources in the nrral areas and the inability to keep up with the development of urban areas such as proposed by several studies of regional disparities (Phillips, 1978). Instead, it assumes that the existence of rural-urban disparities is created by regional development policies, especially for the regional components that can be affected by the 147 process regional development and its underlying policies. The assumption is based on the fact that regional policies applied in the NCR favor urban development (see Section 6.1). This study accepts the fact that distributed regional components resulting from development contribute to the welfare of the region's inhabitants without entering into the debate whether those components are subjective or objective measures of rural-urban disparities. In the literature of regional disparities, assertions about the components distributed are still not conclusive. Some use distribution of income per capita, wealth, or a combination of income and wealth as a measure of regional disparities (Smith, 1982). Others use and develop indicators of well being, quality of life, or standards of living as a measure of regional disparities (Knox, 1974; Kuz, 1978; Schultink, 1992). According to Matthews (1983), the meanings of those equity or quality-of-life measures remain vague and seem to overlap with few clear prescriptions of what is involved in any assessment of them. Therefore, this study uses only the available census data of 1990 as measures of rural-urban disparities. This includes some aspects of economic progress, including, inrprovernents of marketing facilities, educational facilities, and health care facilities which may result from regional development and afi‘ect the well being of the region's inhabitants. The distribution of those measures are assessed using the Gini Coefficients (G03) and the Lorenz curves. The Gini Coeficient is a system measure in which it can describe the magnitude of the distribution with only using one single coeficient. A value of the GC ranges between 0 and 1. The value of GC close to 0 indicates equal distribution and the value of close to 1 indicates unequal distribution. The distribution can also be seen in the Lorenz curve in which the degree of inequality is shown by how far the Lorenz curve 148 departs fiom the diagonal or equal-share line (Smith, 1982). The proportion of the total area below the diagonal that is above the Lorenz curve is also a measure of the GC. Since the GC and Lorenz curve are system measures, the spatial concentration of specific components are measured using Location Quotients (LQ's). Using the LQ’s, the concentration of the components in each sub-region of the NCR can be compared. A value of LQ less than 1 indicates that the sub—region's share in the components in question is less than the region's share; and, the value of LQ more than 1 indicates that the sub- region's share is higher than that of the whole region. The methods used to calculate the values of the GC's and LQ's, and the method used to construct Lorenz curve are presented in Section 3.3.2.4. The data used to analyze rural-urban disparities are 1990 census data. The analysis addresses the results of the development process reflected in the spatial distribution to public benefits. This study does not consider distribution of development benefits among social strata due to limited availability data. 611- Wm Several studies in the NCR indicate that there has been a significant progress in the economy of the region. This progress is indicated by the increased relative share of industries and services with their increased value added contributions to the regional economy (Hill, 1992b, Soemarwoto, 1992). In addition, this study also indicates that in the last ten years there were significant increases in the number of industries of all scales, the percentage of population engaged in the manufacturing sector, the numbers of economic institutions (such as banks), and improvements in public transportation and its I49 infrastructure, educational facilities, and health care facilities (see Table 8 and Table 21). All of the increases indicate a growing regional economy. Since the regional development policies have been in favor of urban development, it is expected that the benefits of growing regional economy are concentrated in urban areas and a small portion of the region's inhabitants. In this study, the benefits of a growing regional economy are indicated by the increased number of households with telephone, electricity, or with television—indicators of the increased household economic well-being. Using these indicators, the spatial distribution of benefits of regional economic development can be assessed. The results of the analysis are summarized in Table 22 and Figure 10. Table 22 summarizes : (i) the Location Quotients (LQ's) of the households with telephone, households with electricity provided by PLN (Perusahaan Listrik Negara)—a monopolistic agency providing electricity to the nation, and households with television for each sub—regions of the NCR; (ii) the Gini Coemcients (GC's) of those indicators in nrral areas, urban areas, and the NCR; (iii) the distribution (percentage) of the indicators and population in each sub-regions of the NCR; and (iv) the cumulative percentages of the indicators and population which indicate the concentration or distribution for specific percentage of population in the region. Figure 10 presents Lorenz curves showing the inequality in the distribution of the NCR households with telephone, electricity, or with television in relation to the NCR population. 150 Table 22. Location Quotients (LQ); Gini Coefficients (GC); Percentage Distribution Number of Telephones (Phone), Houses with Electricity (Elect), Television (TV), and Population (Pop) by Village; and Data for Lorenz Curve in the Cum. % NCR Population 25 El 8 8 8 8 3 8 8 .é W 0 700 mm Om%d‘Aqxuof&.Huyu NCR, 1990. ImtionQuotients Percentage Cumulative Region Q) Distribution Ptarcentages ‘) Phone Elect TV Phone Elect TV m Phone fl Elect TV REL. R1 0.50 0.17 0.26 3.86 1.33 1.97 7.68 85.27 10.39 33.41 10.39 58.22 10.39 R2 0.00 0.41 0.32 0.04 11.16 8.67 27.06 89.31 12.46 39.01 12.46 62.84 12.46 10 0.08 0.74 0.38 2.37 21.27 11.02 28.76 93.17 20.14 43.26 15.04 66.28 15.04 R4 0.12 0.98 0.55 1.75 13.92 7.80 14.27 95.19 27.33 52.32 22.23 70.54 22.23 U1 0.28 1.26 0.59 2.02 9.06 4.26 7.19 95.84 29.91 66.24 26.50 78.34 26.50 U2 0.25 1.65 1.33 0.65 4.25 3.44 2.58 97.59 44.18 87.51 65.26 89.36 65.26 U3 1.95 2.71 2.23 4.04 5.60 4.62 2.07 99.96 72.94 98.67 92.32 98.03 92.32 U4 8.21 3.22 5.60 85.27 33.41 58.22 10.39 100 100 100 100 100 100 Gieroefl'rcient SourceofDatasPopulationCensusof1990 (CC) NCR 0.77 0.30 0.51 ‘) CumulativePercentagesarecalculatedbasedontherankoftheirloeation Rural 0.41 0.18 0.09 quotient values, and are used to construct Lorenz Curve Urban 0.46 0.1_8 0.04 Figure 10. Lorenz Curves for the Distribution of the Households with Telephone, with Electricity, and with Television in Relation to Population, by Sub-regions of the NCR (Source : Table 22) 151 The Gini Coefiicient of the households with telephone in the NCR is 0.77, indicating that households with telephone are unequally distributed in the region. This high value of the GC is also represented by the distance of the Lorenz curve to the equal-share line. The Location Quotient values show that the households with telephone are concentrated in the most urbanized region, U3 and U4 with values of 1.95 and 8.21, respectively. This indicates that most of the households with telephone are located in the most urbanized area (U4). The population of U4 represents only 10.39 percent of the NCR population but enjoys 85.27 percent of total number of telephones in the region. The number of households with telephone between rural and urban areas also seems very unevenly distributed. The total population of the urban areas is 22.23 percent of the NCR population and enjoy 91.98 percent of total telephones in the region. On the other hand, 77.77 percent of the NCR population who live in the rural areas enjoy only 8.02 percent of total telephones in the region. Both within rural and urban areas, the households with telephone are also unequally distributed. These are indicated by high values of Gini Coemcients of the households with telephone both in rural and urban areas of 0.41 and 0.46, respectively. This indicates that, besides urban population, only the elite p0pulation in rural areas enjoys this convenience. The distribution of households with electricity is similar to the distribution of households with telephone and is more concentrated in urban areas. However, its concentration is less than that of households with telephone. The Gini Coefiicient of the households with electricity in the region is 0.30 compared to that of the households with telephone of 0.77. Nevertheless, this GC value also indicates that the households with 152 electricity is unequally distributed in the region. This unequal distribution of households with electricity can also be seen in the Lorenz curve of Figure 10. The values of the LQ's show that the households with electricity are more concentrated in urban areas with the values between 1.26 in U1 and 3.22 in U4 than in rural areas with the values between 0.17 in R1 and 0.98 in R4. Region U4 with a population of 10.39 percent of the regional population enjoys 33 .41 percent of the facility provided by the government. Comparing rural and urban conditions shows that urban areas with population of 22.23 percent of the NCR population enjoy 52.32 percent of the electricity while rural areas with population of 77.77 percent enjoy only 47.68 percent of this convenience. Mthin rural and urban areas, on the other hand, households with electricity seem equally distributed with the same GC value. With the advanced telecommunication technology of satellites and with the capability to cover all Indonesian islands, it is expected that television would be found relatively equallydistnbutedinlndonesia. Thisstudyfindsthatthatiscertairrly notthecasesince there is disparity in the regional distribution of the households with television in the NCR, the most developed region Indonesia. The Gini Coefficient of the households with television in the NCR is 0.51, an indication of unequal distribution. This unequal distribution can also be seen in the Lorenz curve of the households with television of Figure 10. The LQ values also show that the households with telephone are more concentrated in the most urbanized region, U2-4 with values of 1.33, 2.23, and 5.60, respectively. This indicates that most of the households with television are located in the most urbanized 153 area (U4). The U4 with population of only 10.39 percent of the NCR population enjoys 58.22 percent of total television in the region. The distribution of the households with television between rural and urban areas also seems very unequal. Urban areas with a population of only 22.23 percent of the NCR population enjoy 70.54 percent of the total television in the region. Within rural and urban areas, households with telephone are also unequally distributed. These are indicated by high Gini Coefficients of households with telephone in rural and urban areas of 0.41 and 0.46, respectively. This indicates that only the elite population in the rural areas might enjoy this convenience. While, within rural areas and urban areas, households with televisions seem equally distributed with the values of the GC's of 0.09 and 0.04, respectively. The unequal distribution of the three indicators show that the benefits of the growing regional economy of the NCR are enjoyed mostly by urban population and by a small portion of the rural population. 632- W This section assesses the distribution of regional marketing facilities in the NCR. It assesses the distribution of the marketing facilities for agricultural inputs, marketing facilities for agricultural products, and local markets with permanent buildings. Since the NCR is the most established agricultural region in the country, it is expected that marketing facilities for agricultural inputs and outputs would be located in rural areas or equally distributed in the whole region. This study uses number of kiosks selling agricultural inputs (KAI) as an indicator of marketing facility for agricultural inputs 154 and number of kiosks selling agricultural products (KAP) as an indicator of marketing facility for agricultural products. While, market with permanent buildings is used to indicate the degree of government efi‘ort in developing the local economy since all local markets are developed and managed by the government. The results of the analysis are summarized in Table 23 and Figure 11. Table 23 summarizes : (i) the Location Quotients (LQ's) of the markets with permanent buildings (market), kiosks selling agricultural inputs (KAI), and kiosks selling agricultural outputs (KAP) for each sub-regions of the NCR; (ii) the Gini Coeflicients (GC's) of those indicators in rural areas, urban areas, and the NCR; (iii) percentage distribution of the indicators and population in each sub-regions of the NCR; and (iv) cumulative percentages of the indicators and population in the NCR Figure 11 presents Lorenz curves showing the inequality in the distribution of market with permanent buildings (market), kiosks selling agricultural inputs (KAI), and kiosks selling agricultural products (KAP) in relation to the NCR population. Such as expected, the results of the analysis show that kiosks selling agricultural inputs (KAI) and those selling agricultural products are evenly distributed in the region andintherural areas. TheGiniCoeficient ofthe distribution ofKAI intheregion and in rural areas are 0.04 and 0.03, respectively. The Gini Coeficient of KAP, on the other hand, in the region and in rural areas are 0.15 and 0.08, respectively. These indicate that both Kiosk selling Agricultural Inputs (KAI) and Kiosks selling Agricultural Products (KAP) are equally distributed in the region. 155 Table 23. Location Quotients (LQ); Gini Coefficients (GC); Percentage Distribution of Village Marketing Facilities including Number of Markets with Permanent Buildings (Market), Kiosks selling Agricultural Inputs (KAI), Kiosks selling Agricultural Products (KAP), and Population (Pop); and Data for Lorenz Curves in the Northern Coast of West Java (NCR), 1990. Location Quotients Percentage Cumulative Region (LQ) Distribution Percentages ‘) MammMmmma mammal R1 0.42 0.86 0.71 3.20 6.64 5.46 7.68 288010.39 2.93 2.58 6.46 2.58 R2 0.86 0.98 0.75 23.20 26.58 20.20 27.06 34.40 12.97 5.28 4.65 28.28 12.97 R3 0.56 1.07 1.00 16.00 30.75 28.89 28.76 37.60 15.04 20.85 18.92 57.17 41.73 R4 0.67 1.09 0.72 9.60 15.57 10.30 14.27 48.00 22.23 51.60 47.68 62.83 48.92 U1 1.45 1.02 0.79 10.40 7.36 5.66 7.19 71.20 49.29 58.96 54.87 83.03 75.98 U2 2.17 1.14 2.50 5.60 2.93 6.46 2.58 80.80 63.56 85.54 81.93 93.33 90.25 U3 1.55 1.14 0.58 3.20 2.35 1.21 2.07 96.80 92.32 92.18 89.61 98.79 97.93 U4 2.77 0.75 2.10 28.80 7.82 21.82 10.39 100 100 100 100 100 100 Gini Coefficient SourceofData : Population Census of 1990 (GC) NCR 0.26 0.04 0.15 ‘)CumulauvePercentagesarecalculatedbasedcntherankoftheirlocation Rural 0.10 0.03 0.08 quotientvalues,andareusedtoconstructlbrenzCurve Urban 0.13 0.09 0.22 1D ” m +w-_~ g 70 —o—KKAA\IID a. +Mnka g. I) g .. ‘3 .o i E so 10 10 no rs fl II 0 N D 711 N n rm OnSSofMlhet'lgFacfli-a Figure 11. Lorenz Curves for the Distribution of Market with Permanent Building (Market), Kiosks selling Agricultural Inputs (KAI), and Kiosks selling Agricultural Products (KAP) in Relation to Population, by Sub-regions of the NCR (Source : Table 23). 156 Especially for input kiosks, the Lorenz curve shows that the line is close to the equal- share line (Figure 11) indicating that spatial distribution is quite equal. This is also supported by the values of LQ's which are relatively identical for all sub-regions of the NCR. However, the Gini Coefficient of the markets with permanent buildings in the region (0.26) is higher than the other two indicators. This indicates that spatial inequality exist in the distribution of government markets with buildings as presented by the large area between Lorenz curve and equal-share line of Figure 11. The values of LQ's show that markets with permanent buildings are more concentrated in urban areas with values between 1.45 and 2.77 as compared to nrral areas with values between 0.42 and 0.67. Urban areas with population of 22.23 percent of the NCR population enjoy 48.00 percent of facilities while rural areas with population of 77.77 percent enjoy only 52 percent of the facilities. The distribution of the three indicators shows that marketing facilities developed by the government (markets with permanent buildings) tend to concentrate in urban areas while marketing facilities developed through the private initiatives (KAI and KAP) tend to be more equally distributed in the NCR. 157 6.2.3. Edgcationg! Facilities This section describes the distribution of pre-college educational facilities in the NCR which includes the number of elementary schools, the number of secondary schools, and the number of high schools. The results of the analysis are presented in Table 24 and Figure 12. Table 24 summarizes : (i) the Location Quotients (LQ's) of elementary schools (Elsch), secondary school (Secsch), and high school (Hisch) for each sub-regions of the NCR; (ii) the Gini Coeficients (GC's) of the indicators in rural areas, urban areas, and the NCR; (iii) percentage distribution of the indicators and population in each sub-regions of the NCR; and (iv) cumulative percentages of the indicators and population in the NCR. Figure 12 presents Lorenz curves showing the inequality in the distribution of number of elementary schools, secondary schools, and high schools in relation to the NCR population. The Gini Coefficient of elementary school the NCR is 0.04 indicating the elementary schools are evenly distributed in the region such as presented by its Lorenz curve which is close to the equal-share line of Figure 12. Although all values of the LQ's in the urban areas are higher than those in rural areas, the difi‘erences are very small indicating that the elementary school are evenly distributed in all sub-regions of the NCR. Both within rural and urban areas, elementary schools are evenly distributed with the GC values of 0.01 and 0.05, respectively. 158 In contrast to the distribution of elementary schools, the distribution of secondary schools are more concentrated in urban areas with a regional GC value of 0.23. This is also reflected by The Lorenz curve (Figure 12). Table 24. Location Quotients (LQ); Gini Coefficients (GC); Percentage Distribution of Village Educational Facilities including Number of Elementary Schools (Elsch), Secondary Schools (Secsch), High School (Hisch), and Population (Pop); and Data for Lorenz Curves in the Northern Coast of West Java (NCR), 1990. Cumulative Pecan of NCR Population ,eaaesaass § a 3 B 8 1D I) WWW M 1m Location Quotients Percentage Cumulative Region (LQ) __ Distribution Percentages ‘) Elsch Secsch Hisch ElschISecsch Hisch _PoL Elsch M [Secsch Pop Hisch Pop R1 0.98 0.39 0.18 7.50 3.04 1.35 7.68 2.71 2.07 29.49 10.39 50.22 10.39 R2 0.95 0.63 0.38 25.64 16.97 10.31 27.06 15.85 12.46 32.72 12.46 56.50 12.46 R3 0.96 0.82 0.42 27.68 23.64 12.11 28.76 19.01 15.04 43.02 19.65 66.81 19.65 R4 0.91 0.78 0.44 13.05 11.11 6.28 14.27 26.13 22.23 45.24 22.23 69.95 22.23 U1 0.99 1.43 1.43 7.12 10.30 10.31 7.19 33.63 29.91 68.88 50.99 76.23 36.50 U2 1.22 0.86 1.22 3.16 2.22 3.14 2.58 61.31 58.67 79.99 65.26 88.34 65.26 U3 1.31 1.56 3.03 2.71 3.23 6.28 2.07 86.95 85.73 96.96 92.32 98.65 92.32 U4 1.26 2.84 4.83 13.14 29.49 50.22 10.39 100 100 100 100 100 100 Gieroefiicient SourceofDatarPopulation Censusoi 1990 (GC) NCR 0.04 0.23 0.48 ‘)Cumu1ativePercentagesareca1culatedbasedontherankoftheirlocation Rural 0.01 0.08 0.06 quotient values, and are used to construct Lorenz Curve Urban 0.05 0.18 0.25 Figure 12. Lorenz Curves for the Distribution of the Number of Elementary Schools (Elsch), Secondary Schools (Secsch), and High Schools (Hisch) in Relation to Population, by Sub-regions of the NCR (Source : Table 24) 159 The Location Quotients show that secondary schools are the most concentrated in the most urbanized area (U4) with a LQ value of 2.84 followed by U3 with the LQ value of 1.56 and U1 with the LO value of 1.43. The Gini Coefficient of high schools in the NCR is 0.48 indicating an uneven spatial distribution of high schools in the region. This unequal distribution can also be seen in the Lorenz curves of high schools of Figure 12. The values of LQ's show that high schools are clearly most concentrated in the urban areas (Ul-4) with values ranging between 1.22 in U2 and 4.83 in U4. The share of the regional population for urban areas is only 22.23 percent but they contain 69.95 percent of high schools in the region. In addition, high schools among urban sun-regions are not evenly distributed such as indicated by the GC value of .25. The distribution of the three indicators of educational development in the NCR shows a clear hierarchical distribution of public educational facilities. This distribution reflects an educational development policy with basic educational facilities equally distributed in the region with a concentration secondary educational facilities in several regional centers with the notion that a rural populations who wish to pursue higher education are expected to go to the regional centers. 160 6.2-4- W This section describes the distribution of health care facilities in the NCR including the number of physicians, traditional midwives, and total number of health care providers which is the summation of number of hospitals, polyclinics, clinics, maternity centers, and community health care centers. It is important to note that traditional midwives in the region provided an extended services to local communities in addition to perform delivery, such as a general treatment of other illnesses. The results of the analysis are summarized in Table 25 and Figure 13. Table 25 summarizes : (i) the Location Quotients (LQ's) number of physicians, traditional midwives (mwife), and total health care providers (care) for each sub-regions of the NCR; (ii) the Gini Coeficients (GC's) of the indicators in nrral areas, urban areas, and the NCR; (iii) percentage distribution of the indicators and population in each sub-regions of the NCR; and (iv) cumulative percentages of the indicators and population in the NCR. Figure 13 presents Lorenz curve showing inequality in the distribution of physicians, traditional nridwives, and health care providers in relation to the NCR population. The Gini Coefficient of physicians in the NCR is 0.63 indicating that physicians are unevenly distributed over the region. Physicians in the region are concentrated in the most urbanized region (U4) with the value of LQ of 6.74 followed by U2 with the value of 2.43. The urban areas (U 14) which share to the regional population of only 22.23 percent have 80.50 percent of physicians in the region. The rural areas, on the other hand, which share regional population of 77.77 percent have only 19.50 percent of physicians in 161 Table 25. Location Quotients (LQ); Gini Coefficients (GC); Percentage Distribution of Village Availability of Health Care Facilities including Number of Physician (Physician), Traditional Midwives (Mwife), Health Care Providers (Care), and Population (Pop); and Data for Lorenz Curves in the Northern Coast of West Java (NCR), 1990. LoeationQuotients Percentage Cumulative lRegion (LQ) Distribution Percentaes‘) PhEMwifeCare Mwife!Care£P_hys_Pop_MwifeliP_— 2.0 ha dryland and those with the same hectarage of paddy land decreased by 58.04 percent and 49.56 percent, respectively. The analysis also shows that the urbanization is accompanied by increased absentee land ownership. At the regional level, the total absentee lands and the number of absentee land owners increased very significantly by 193.20 percent and 43.26 percent or by annual increases of 19.30 percent and 4.33 percent, respectively. The total hectarage of absentee lands increased faster than the number of absentee landlords, indicating more concentrated absentee land ownership. The increased absentee lands can be attributed mostly to an increase in absentee dryland rather than to an increase in absentee paddyland. Absentee dryland in the region increased by 605.94 percent during the period of 1982-1992 or 60.59 percent annually. Absentee paddyland, meanwhile, increased 42.29 percent during the same period or 4.23 percent annually. This pattern of increase in absentee dryland is accompanied by a higher number of absentee landlords acquiring dryland than those acquiring paddyland. Average number of absentee land owners with dryland increased by 229.34 percent or 22.93 percent annually and those with of paddde increased only by 18.49 percent or 1.85 percent annually. While it is more economical to invest in paddyland than that in dryland, the high increase of absentee dryland in the NCR might be attributed to the increased land speculation in the region because the land speculators usually have on-hand information regarding rural lands allocated for urban uses which is rarely an irrigated land. This is ’E 172 especially important given existing the Government of Indonesia's policies prohibiting conversion of paddyland to non-agricultural uses. In the rural areas, changes in absentee land ownership are more staggering than those in the region as a whole. The total absentee lands and the number of absentee land owners during 1982-1992 have increased by 192.96 percent and 34.77 percent or 19.30 percent. Comparing the total hectarage of absentee lands (dryland and paddyland), the analysis shows that absentee dryland increased by 638.06 percent or 63.81 percent annually. Absentee paddyland, meanwhile, increased by 29.78 percent or 2.98 percent annually. This pattern is also accompanied by a higher number of absentee land owners acquiring dryland rather than paddyland. The number of absentee land owners with dryland increased by 460.18 percent or 46.02 percent annually while those with paddyland did not increase significantly, indicating that the absentee paddyland in rural areas is also becoming more concentrated in the hand of absentee owners. The analysis of agricultural land conversion along with the urbanization process in the region shows that, at the regional level, the irrigated land decreased by 25.62 percent during the period of 1982-1992 or 2.56 percent annually while the agricultural dryland decreased by 27.11 percent or 2.71 percent annually. In the rural areas, the irrigated land decrease by 25.04 percent during the period of analysis or 2.50 percent annually while the agricultural dryland did not decrease significantly. This indicates that agricultural land conversion in the rural areas includes mostly irrigated land, a pillar of regional agricultural production. 173 At the regional level, the increased irrigated land conversion has put additional pressures on the NCR capability to maintain its key role as the bread basket of Indonesia. At the household level, however, this study finds that the households involved in land conversion are better ofi‘. The total household income increased by 37.58 percent by converting the land. This study also finds that land conversion in the NCR is mostly dictated by market price mechanism and that government policy does not significantly afi‘ect household decisions regarding land conversion. Regarding the analysis of structural changes in the village employment, this study finds that there exist five fundamental differences between rural and regional structural changes of employment. First, in the period of 1982-1992, rural employment is still dominated by agricultural employment. Second, the percentage of agricultural labor in rural areas increases significantly at 22.04 percent. This increase is much higher than that in the region at only 0.95 percent. Third, although employment in the manufacturing sector in rural areas increased very significantly, the increase is higher than that in the region at 147 .73 percent and 87.62 percent, respectively, but its absolute value is much less than that of the region. Forth, the increase of small scale enterprise is higher in rural areas than that in the region at 65.55 percent and 47.28 percent, respectively. Finally, the employment ratio in private enterprises in the rural areas is much less than that in the region as a whole. These figures imply that, at the regional level : (i) a decrease of the employment in the agricultural related activities is followed by a significant increase in the employment in the manufacturing industries and small scale enterprises; and (ii) a decrease in the percentage 174 of self—employed farmer is not followed by an increase in employment in the agricultural sector, an indication that manufacturing industries and small scale enterprises have the capacity to absorb farmers displaced from the agricultural sector. Meanwhile, for rural areas the figures imply that : (i) a decrease of the employment in the agricultural sector is not followed by a significant increase in the employment in the manufacturing sectors; and (ii) a decrease in the percentage of self-employed farmers is followed by an increase in employment in agricultural laborer and small scale enterprises, an indication that displaced farmers in rural areas are either being employed as fiiture agricultural laborers or entering the labor force of small scale enterprises. 4. WM Degree of regional industrialization is measured by changes in the numbers of large scale industries, medium scale industries, and small scale industries. Large scale industry is defined as an industry with more than or equal to 100 employees. Medium scale industry is defined as an industry with more than or equal to 20 but less than 100 employees. Small scaleindustryisdefinedasanindustrywithmorethanorequalto5butlessthan20 employees. This study finds that during the period of 1982-1992 the degree of industrialization has increased very significantly. The number of large scale industries increased by 4750.50 percent during the period or 475.05 percent annually, an increase from 0.0909 in 1982 to 4.4091. The mrmber of medium scale industries increased by 259.36 percent during the period or 25.94 percent annually, an increase fi'om 0.7273 in 1982 to 2.6136 in 1992. The number ofsmall scale industries increased by 81.34 percent during the period or 8.13 percent annually, an increase fiom 6.0909 in 1982 to 11.0455 in 175 1992. These figures show that the development of medium and large scale industries in the region occurs just recently, in the last ten years, indicating recent growing regional economy. 5. Rural-Qrbg Dispm'ties The study finds that there exists rural-urban disparity in the distribution of the benefits regional economic progress in 1990. This is indicated by the high values of the Gini Coemcients (GC) of households with telephone, electricity, or with television in which their GC values are 0.77, 0.30, and 0.51 percent respectively. The economic progress in the region is more concentrated in urban areas since the Location Quotients (LQ) of the three indicators are higher in urban areas than those in nrral areas. The marketing facilities of the kiosks selling agricultural inputs and those selling agricultural products are evenly distributed in the region with the GC values of 0.04 and 0.15, respectively. However, markets with permanent building are unevenly distributed in the region with the GC of 0.26 and most of them are concentrated in urban areas such as indicated by its LQ which is higher in urban areas than in rural areas. The elementary schools are evenly distributed in the region with the GC of 0.04 and the LQ's of relatively similar between nrral and urban areas. The secondary schools are unevenly distributed in the region with the GC of 0.23 with concentration mostly in urban areas indicated by its LQ which is higher in urban areas than in nrral areas. The high schools, meanwhile, are also unevenly distributed in the region with higher GC of 0.48 with concentration mostly in urban areas indicated by its LQ which is higher in urban areas than in rural areas. 176 The study also finds that physicians are mostly concentrated in urban areas in which with only 22.23 percent of regional population, the urban areas enjoy 80.50 percent of the physician in the region (GC = 0.63). On the other hand, traditional midwives and total health care providers are evenly distributed in the region with GC's of 0.03 and 0.12, respectively. 7.2. Policy Implications Research findings suggest that without any further government policy interventions in both regional and agricultural development future agricultural sustainability cannot be maintained. This implies that the role of this region as the bread basket of Indonesia will be threatened. Therefore, the urbanization process in the region is undermining the filture of Indonesia's self-suficiency in rice. More importantly, the welfare of the population engaged in agricultural related activities which is 49.28 percent of regional population or 75.88 percent of total rural p0pulation (1992) will also be afi‘ected by the process. These assertions are supported by the research findings which show that urban and industrial development have displaced self-employed farmers through increased agricultural land conversion and increased absentee land ownership. The logical adjustment process commonly pursued by rural population is to disaggregate the household agricultural land by means of land conversion and land sales. This land parcelization results in diseconomies of scale in agricultural enterprises which provides for additional disincentive for rural population to remain in agriculture. The combined efl‘ects of increased agricultural land conversion, increased absentee land ownership, and increased land parcelization will decrease both regional agricultural productivity and I77 agricultural production. 0n the other hand, the increased degree of regional industrialization has been unable to absorb the population displaced fi'om the agricultural sector. Consequently, they enter the labor force of small scale enterprises or remain in agriculture as laborers. Since these last forms of employment are characterized by low economic productivity, the urbanization process, indirectly, diminishes the welfare of nrral population. The research findings also suggest that the existing urbanization process will complicate problems of regional development. The NCR regional development is pursued through a growth center policy, urbanization is induced by a combination of direct public investments and capital subsidies to private enterprises to create urban centers which are expected to difi‘use economic growth into rural areas. The research findings show that the expected trickle down efi‘ects into rural areas does not occur in the NCR. In fact, the economic progress and development of public facilities are still concentrated in the urban areas such as presented by the analysis of rural-urban disparities. Moreover, urbanization intheregionismostlydeterminedbypushfactorsfi'omagriculturalruralareasinstead of caused by increased opportunities in urban areas. This implies that, without further government intervention, future rural-urban dispmties will increase and that increased economic stress in agricultural nrral areas will drive resource flow into urban areas, creating further rural-urban disparities. To sustain the role of this region as the bread basket of Indonesia and to improve the welfare of rural population engaged in agricultural related activities, government must, I78 therefore, initiate a broad-based rural development strategy. The strategy must include policies on : 1. Agljfllturfl land consolidation. Agricultural land consolidation is mainly directed to mitigate negative effects of diseconomies of scale in agricultural enterprises which commonly create disincentives for the rural population to remain in agriculture. It is urgently needed in the region for two fundamental reasons, namely : (i) current regional industrial and high productivity service sectors are still unable to absorb population displaced from the agricultural sector, and (ii) to maintain and improve regional agricultural productivity and outputs by creating economies of scale in agricultural enterprises. 2. ' ' ' ' ' ultural l d conversion. This policy should be pursued by the government through indirect policy measures instead of by introducing legislation which in reality is diflicult if not impossible to enforce. This study shows that household decisions on land conversion are mainly dictated by land prices and, in fact, increase farm household welfare. Since this is a decision dictated purely by economic motives, a direct measure such as the Presidential Decree will be unable to afi‘ect household decisions regarding land conversion. Assuming that such decree can be enforced, field observations show that farm households actually change the status of irrigated to non- irrigated land by making the land idle around two years and subsequently convert this land to non-agricultural uses. l79 3. Minimizing absentee land ownership. This policy is directed to make agricultural enterprises in rural areas economically competitive so that there is no incentive to sell land. 4. Strengthening rurm. This study shows that urbanization is mostly affected by push factors associated with rural life. Therefore, to indirectly reduce urban migration, rural areas must be developed to balance urban attraction. The integrated rural development involving four potential policy initiatives above can be approached by two scenarios: 1. Scenario I : The government still maintains the current regional development strategy, _ namely a growth center policy in which urbanization is induced by a ' combination of direct public investments and capital subsidies to private enterprises to create urban centers which are expected to diffuse economic growth into rural areas. Under this scenario, rural development is pursued along with urban development (Rondinelli, 1983). Within this framework, the notion of linkages between rural and urban areas is viewed as very crucial for rural development since major markets for agricultural surpluses are in urban centers, while the public services are commonly in ‘ Li? l located in urban areas. Instead of focusing investments exclusively on rural areas or urban areas, investment is diversified over space in such manner that secondary cities can be created to build linkages between nrral areas and secondary cities and between secondary cities and urban centers. In other words, the focus of this scenario is to create generative secondary cities which are expected to : (i) relieve pressures on the largest cities; (ii) reduce regional inequalities since it is expected that secondary cities will difi‘use the benefits of urbanization; (iii) stimulate the rural economy through the 180 provision of public services, enlarging rural market, and facilitating the absorption of agricultural surplus of labor by urban centers; (iv) provide an increased regionally decentralized administrative capacity; and (v) help alleviate poverty in intermediate- sized cities (Rondinelli, 1983). If the expected roles of the generative secondary cities can be met in the NCR development, the agricultural sector will develop as a result of expanded local markets for agricultural products. It discourages, indirectly, agricultural land conversion since agriculture will remain profitable. In turn, it reduces land parcelization which commonly results from land conversion. More importantly, this strategy may result in a higher quality of rural life and indirectly will reduce urbanization. ‘ 2. Scenario H : The government still maintains current regional development strategies but gives greater autonomy to local authorities create land use planning initiatives (Scenario I + greater local autonomy). Under this scenario, scenario I is broadened with increased local autonomy to determine local land use destinations. Therefore, in addition to developing generative secondary cities, the local government must develop regional land use planning and control so that factors afi‘ecting regional agricultural sustainability identified in this study can be addressed directly and efi‘ectively. Planning must reflect regional agricultural development goals and its undermining factors in maintaining the region‘s position as the bread basket of Indonesia. The system of rewards and penalties is to be incorporated within the fiamework of land use control. The government may buy land development rights from the people who intend to convert their land to non-agricultural uses to ensure that land remains in agricultural production. The government may also 181 introduce agricultural tax incentives for agricultural development. Similarly, the government may subsidize the agricultural sector in the provision of agricultural inputs and marketing of agricultural products, and improve the rural infrastructure. These policy instruments may reduce agricultural land conversion which undermines the sustainability of agricultural (development) in the region. 7.3. Needs for Further Research Further research related to this study may address: (1) proposed policy recommendations summarized in Section 7.2., (ii) impacts of urbanization on agricultural development not discussed directly in this study and viewed as very important for firture agricultural development in the NCR, and (iii) research related to the fact that the NCIL both as a corridor region adjoining two big cities Jakarta and Cirebon and as major food production region, faces fundamental changes due to the urbanization of the areas surrounding Jakarta and Cirebon. 1. Further Research Related to Proposed Polig Recommendations Policies directed to agricultural land consolidation may accentuate populations displaced from agriculture. Therefore, before pursuing these policies, further research is needed to: (i) determine the optimum size of land holdings subject to specific level of agricultural employment and a specific minimum level of income for rural populations, and (ii) assess the impacts of land consolidation. In pursuing policies to minimize agricultural land conversion, the government needs to initiate research to identify direct and indirect policy measures which guarantee the improved profitability of agricultural enterprises. 182 2. Further Research Relrged to Impacts of Urbanization on Regional Agicultural Development Other prominent impacts of urbanization on agricultural development such as the changes in the quality of the agricultural resource base as a result of intensive use, soil and water pollution impacts, and other cumulative environmental impacts of fertilizer and pesticide use need to be addressed. This additional research is needed to evaluate more comprehensive impacts of urbanization on agricultural development. 3. Further Research Related to the NCR as a Changing Corridor Regjga At the regional level, furthermore, the government must adopt and develop comprehensive measures to deal with urban industrial development and agricultural development in the hinterlands. To design a comprehensive strategy to deal with changes in the NCR, the following macro and micro studies are needed to analyze : (i) the magnitudes of the social and economic changes in the NCR; (ii) changes in land use patterns and land prices in the area immediately surrounding major cities as well as in rural areas; (iii) changes in relationships among the region and the metropolitan centers; (iv) changes in regional socio-economic conditions and its impacts on migration—both internal migration in the region and migration to metropolitan centers; (v) changes in settlement patterns; (vi) changes in environmental quality; and (vii) changes in rural-urban linkages within the region and changes in the urbanized area-metropolitan center linkages. These research recommendations do not necessarily provide a complete list of research priorities. '- 1?? - , - A r BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Amin, Samir. 1974. Accumulation on a World Scale: A Critique of the Theory of Underdevelopment. 2 Vols. New York: Monthly Review Press. Amin, Samir. 1976. Unequal Development. New York: Monthly Review Press. Andersen, Per Pinstrup and Peter B. R. Hazell. 1985. The Impact of the Green Revolution and Prospects for the Future. Food Reviews International, 1(1): 1-25. Armstrong, Warwick and T.G. McGee. 1985. Theatres of Accumulation: Studies in Asian and Latin American Urbanization. New York : Methuen & Co. Atkinson, Adrian. 1992. The Urban Bioregion as Sustainable Development Paradigm. Ihird world Planning Review 14(4):327-3 54. Baran, Paul. 1979. On the Politicd Economy of Backwardness. In Wilber, Charles K. (Ed), The Political Economy of Development and Underdevelopment. New York: Random House. Pp. 91-102. Barber, Gerald M. 1988. Elementary Statistics for Geographer. New York: The Guilford Press. Batty, Michael. 1976. Urban Modelling: Alogorithms, Calrbrations, Predictions. Cambridge : Cambridge University Press. Beckford, George L. 1979. Comparative Rural Systems, Development and Underdevelopment. In Wilber, Charles K. (Ed), The Political Economy of Development and Underdevelopment. Second Edition. New York: Random House. Berry, B.J.L. and AM. Baker. 1968. Geographic Sampling. In Berry, B.J.L and DE Marble. 1968. Spatial Analysis : A Reader in Statistical Geography. Prentice Hall. Pp. 24-34. Berry, Brian J .L. 1964. Approaches to Regional Analysis: A Synthesis. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 54:2-11. Berry, Brian J.L. 1981. Comparative Urbanization: Divergent Paths in the Twentieth Century. Revised Edition. New York: St. Martin's Press. Bhadra, Dipasis and ASP. Brandao. 1993. Urbanization, Agricultural Development, and Land Allocation. World Bank Discussion Papers, No. 201, The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA 183 184 Bhooshan, BS. and RP. Misra. 1980. Role of Small and Intermediate Towns in the Development of Mandya District. In Bhooshan, B.S. (Ed), Toward Alternative Settlement Strategies. New Delhi, India: Heritage Publishers. Blair, John P. 1991. Urban and Regional Economics. Homwood, Illinois and Boston, Massachussetts : Irwin. Booth, Anne (Ed). 1992. The Oil Boom and Afier : Indonesian Economic Policy and Performance in the Soehalto Era. New York: Oxford University Press. Booth, Anne. 1988. Agricultural Development in Indonesia. Sydney: Allen and Unwin. Breese, Gerald (Ed). 1966. City in Newly Developing Countries: Readings on Urbanism and Urbanization. Englewood Clifi‘s, NJ: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Brinser, Ayers. 1976. Essays on Natural Resource Management. Compiled and Edited by Nickel, Paul E. and Marylin M. Wallace. The Natural Resource Institute, University of Manitoba, Winnipeg, Manitoba, Canada. Bryant, C. and White, LG. 1982. Managing Development in the Third World. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. Choc, Sang-Chuel. 1981. Korea : From Chaos to Progress. Chapter 5, in Honjo, M. (ed), Urbanization and Regional Development. Maruzen Asia: United Nations Center for Regional Development, Nagoya, Japan. Chuta, Enyinna and Cari Liedholm. 1990. Rural Small-Scale Industry: Empirical Evidence and Policy Issues. Chapter 19, in Eicher, Carl K. and John M. Staatz (Eds), Agricultural Development in the Third World. Second Edition. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. Pp. 327-341. Coates, B.E., RJ. Johnson, and PL. Knox. 1977. Geography and Inequality. New York: Oxford University Press. Colman, D. and F. Nelson. 1978. Economics of Change in Less Developed Countries. Oxford: Philip Allan. Cowell, F. 1977. Measuring Inequality : Techniques for the Social Sciences. New York : Wiley and Sons. Cramer, Gail L. and Clarence W. Jensen. 1988. Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness. Fourth Edition. New York: John Wiley and Sons. Dadzie, K.K.S. 1980. Economic Development. Scientific American Vol. 243, No. 3., September. 185 Datta, Satya. 1990. Why a New Approach to Third World Urbanization. In Datta, Satya (Ed), Third World Urbanization. Swedish Council for Research in thr Humanities and Social Sciences, Stockholm. Pp. 9-23. DESFIL. (No Date). Beyond the Project: The Quest for Sustainability in the Third World. Working Paper of Development for Fragile Lands. Dicken, Peter and Peter E. Lloyd. 1990. Location in Space. Third Edition. New York : Harper Collins Publishers. Douglas, GK. 1984. The Meaning of Agricultural Sustainability. In GK. Douglas (Ed), Agricultural Sustainability in a Changing World Order. Westview Special Studies in Agriculture Science and Policy. Pp. 3-29. Dunford, Richard W. 1981. Farmland Retention : Efiiciency vs Equity. In Jeske, Walter E. (Ed), Economics, Ethics, Ecology : Roots of Productive Conservation. Iowa: Soil Conservation Society of America. Pp. 367-3 79. Eicher, Carl K. and John M. Staatz. 1990. Agricultural Development in the Third World. Second Edition. Baltimore : John Hopkins University Press. El-Bushra, El-Sayed. 1989. The Urban Crisis and Rural-Urban Migration in Sudan. In Potter RB. and T. Unwin (Eds), The Geography of Urban-Rural Interaction in Developing Countries. London: Routledge. Pp. 109-140. ELShakhs, S. 1976. Planning for Systems of Settlements in Emerging Nations. Town Plarming Review 7(1): 127-138. Ellis, G.F.R 1980. Quality of Life Concept: An Overall Framework for Assessment Schemes. Saldru Working Paper No. 30. Enke, Stephen. 1962a. Industrialization through Greater Productivity in Agriculture. Review of Economics and Statistics 44(February):88-91. Enke, Stephen. 1962b. Economic Development with Limited and Unlimited Supplies of Labor. Oxford Economic Papers 14(June): 158-172. Erwidodo. 1990. Panel Data Analysis on Farm-Level Efiiciency, Input Demand and Output Supply of Rice Farming in West Java, Indonesia. A Doctoral Dissertation. Department of Agricultural Econonrics, Michigan State University. Firman, Tommy. 1992. The Spatial Pattern of Urban Population eroth in Java, 1980- 1990. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 28(2):95-109. 186 Frank, Andre Gunder. 1979. The Development of Underdevelopment. In Wilber, Charles K. (Ed), The Political Economy of Development and Underdevelopment. New York : Random House. Pp. 103-113. Friedman, John. 1966. Two Concepts of Urbanization. Urban Aflairs Quarterly 1:78-84. Friedman, John. 1973. Urbanization, Planning, and National Development. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications. Friedman, John (Ed). 1974. New Concepts and Technologies in Third World Urbanization. Graduate School of Architecture and Urban Planning, university of California, Los Angeles. Friedman, John. 1980. Urban Bias in Regional Development Policy. Graduate School of Architecture and Urban Planning, university of califomia, Los Angeles. Friedman, John. 1988. Life Space and Economic Space. New Brunswick, New Jersey : Transaction Books. Friedman, John and Clyde Weaver. 1979. Territory and Function : The Evolution of Regional Planning. Berkeley and Los Angeles : University of California Press. Friedman, John and Goetz Wolfi‘. 1982. World City Formation: An Agenda for Research and Action. Graduate School of Architecture and Urban Planning, University of California, Los Angeles. Getis, Arthur and Barry Boots. 1978. Models of Spatial Processes. New York: Cambridge University Press. Gillis M., D.H. Perkins, M. Roemer, and DR Snodgrass. 1987. Economics of Development. Second Edition. New York: W.W. Norton & Company. Gluck, Peter R. and RC. Meister. 1979. Cities in Transition: Social Changes and Institutional Responses in Urban Development. New York: New Viewpoints, A Division of Franklin Watts. Goldberg, Michael and Peter Chinloy. 1984. Urban Land Economics. Toronto : John Wiley & Sons. Golstein, Sidney and David Sly. 1974. Basic Data Needed for the Study of Urbanization. International Union for the Scientific Study of Population. Gottman, Jean. 1961. Megapolis. Cambridge : Masachussetts Institute of Technology Press. I87 Gould, Peter R. 1972. Pedagogic Review : Entropy in Urban and Regional Modelling. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 62:289-700. Government of West Java (Pemerinath Propinsi Daerah Tingkat I Jawa Barat). 1990. Pola Dasar Pembangungan Daerah : Propinsi Daerah Tingkat I Jawa Barat 1989/ 1990-1993/ 1994. Pemerintah Propinsi Daerah Tingkat I Jawa Barat. Harner, A.M., AD. Steer, and D.G. Williams. 1986. Indonesia : The Challenge of Urbanization. World Bank Stafi‘ Working Papers, No. 787, The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA. Hardjono, Joan. 1983. Rural Development in Indonesia: the 'top—down' approach. Chapter 2, In Lea, D.A.M. and DP. Chaudhri (Eds), Rural Development and the State: Contradictions and Dilemmas in Developing Countries. New York: Methuen & Co, Ltd. Hardoy, J.E. and D. Satterthwaite. 1986. Why Small and Intermediate Urban Centers?. In Hardoy, J .E. and D. Satterthwaite (Eds), Small and Intermediate Urban Centers : Their Role in Regional and National Development in the Third World. London : Hodder and Stoughton in Association with the International Institute for Environment and Development. Pp. 1-17. Hanison, Lawrence E. 1985. Underdevelopment is a State of Mind. The Center for International Afl‘airs, Harvard University and Madison Books. Hauser, Philip M. 1985. Introduction and Overview. Chapter 1, in Hauser, Philip M., Daniel B. Suits, and Naohiro Ogawa (Eds), Urbanization and Migration in Asian Development. Tokyo: National Institute for Reserach Advancement. Hauser, Philip M., Daniel B. Suits, and Naohiro Ogawa. 1985. Urbanization and Migration in Asian Development. Tokyo: National Institute for Reserach Advancement. Hayami, Y. and V.W. Ruttan. 1985. Agricultural Development: An International Perspective. Revised and Expanded Edition. Baltimore, Maryland: The John Hopkins University Press. Hehanussa, PE. and F. Hehuwat. 1979. Morphogenesis of the Northern Coastal Plain of West Java between Cirebon and Jakarta : Its Implications for Coastal Zone Management. In Bird, E.C.F. and A. Soegiarto (Eds). 1979. Proceeding of the Jakarta Workshop on Coastal Resources Management. Pp. 22-30. Helmer, John and Neil A Eddington (Eds). 1973. Urbanman: The Psychology of Urban Survival. New York: Free Press, A Division of Macmillan Publishing Co., Inc. 188 Henderson, JV. 1977. Economic Theories and the Cities. New York : Academic Press. Hill, Hal. 1992a. Regional development in a Boom and Bust Petroleum Economy: Indonesia since 1970. Economic Development and Cultural Change 40(2):351-377. Hill, Hal. 1992b. Manufacturing Industry. Chapter 7, in Booth, Anne (Ed), The Oil Boom and Afier: Indonesian Economic Policy and Performance in the Soeharto Era. New York: Oxford University Press. Hirschman, Albert 0. 1958. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven: Yale University Press. Honjo, M. 1980. Role of Government in Regional Development. Regional Development Dialogue 121-l6. Honjo, M. 1981a. Introduction. Chapter 1, in Honjo, M. (Ed) Urbanization and Regional Development. Maruzen Asia: United Nations Center for Regional Development, Nagoya, Japan. Honjo, M. 1981b. Overview of Urbanization and Metropolitanization in Asia. Chapter 2, in Honjo, M. (Ed) Urbanization and Regional Development. Maruzen Asia: United Nations Center for Regional Development, Nagoya, Japan. Hugo, Graeme J. 1978. Population Mobility in West Java. Yogyakarta: Gadjah Mada University Press. Ikerd, J.E. 1989. Conflicts between Sustainability and Profitability in Agriculture. Unpublished Paper. Paper on Seminar Series in Sustainable Development, MSU; Winter 1990. Ilahude, AG. 1979. The Oceanographic Features of the Coastal Region between Jakarta and Cirebon : Oceanography. In Bird, E.C.F. and A. Soegiarto (Eds). 1979. Proceeding ofthe Jakarta Workshop on Coastal Resources Management. Pp. 31-35. James, William E. 1985. ASEAN Agriculture and Economic Development. Chapter 2, in Hauser, P.M. (Ed), Urbanization and Migration in Asean Development. Tokyo: National Institute for Research Advancement. Johnston, BF. and J.W. Mellor. 1961. The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development. American Economic Review 51:566-593. Johnston, RJ. 1991. Multivariate Statistical Analysis in Geography. New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc. 189 Jorgenson, Dale W. 1961. The Development of a Dual Economy. Economic Journal 72(June):309-334. Jorgenson, Dale W. 1969. The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development: Classical versus Neoclassical Models of Growth. In Wharton Jr., Clifion R., Subsistence Agriculture and Economic Development. Chicago: Aldine. Pp. 320-48. Kabwegyere, T.B. 1979. Small Urban Centers and the Growth of Underdevelopment in Rural Kenya. In Southall, A. (ed), Small Urban Centers in Rural Development in Afiica. Afiican Studies Program, University of “fisconsin, Madison, Wisconsin. Pp. 36—44. Kelley, Allen C. and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 1982. The Limits of Urban Growth : Suggestions for Macromodelling Third World Economics Economic Development and Culture Change, 30(April):595—623. Killen, James. 1983. Mathematical Programming Methods for Geographers and Planners. NewYork: St Martin's Press. Kleinbaum, David G. and Lawrence L. Kupper. 1978. Applied Regression Analysis and Other Multivariable Methods. North Scituate, Massachusetts: Duxbury Press. Knox, Paul L. 1974. Level of Living : A Conceptual Framework for Monitoring Regional Variations in Well-being. Regional Studies 8:11-19. Kuz, Tony J. 1978. Quality of Life : An Objective and Subjective Variable Analysis. Regional Studies 12:409-417. Land, Kenneth C. and Seymour Spilerman (Eds). 1975. Social Indicator Model. New York: Russell sage Foundation. Lele, SM. 1991. Sustainable Development: A Critical Review. World Development 19(6):607-621. Lipton, M. 1982. Why Poor People Stay Poor. In Harris, J. (Ed). Rural Develelopment: Theories of Peasant Economy and Agrarian Change. London : Hutchinson. Pp. 66- 81. Little, Ian MD. 1982. Economic Development: Theory, Policy, and International Relations. New York: Basic Books, Inc., Publishers. Lockeretz, William. 1986. Alternative Agriculture. Chapter 13, in Dahlberg, Kenneth A. (Ed), New Directions for Agriculture and Agricultural Reserach : Neglected Dimensions and Emerging Alternatives. New Jersey : Rowman & Allanheld Publishers. Pp. 291-311. “ “ “flew 190 Mabogunje, AL. 1981. The Development Process: A Spatial Perspective. New York: Holmes and Meier Publications. Manning, Chris. 1988. The Green Revolution, Employment, and Economic Change in Rural Java: Reassessment of Trends under the New Order. Asean Economic Research Unit, Institute of Southeast Asian Studies. Marshall, John U. 1989. The Structure of Urban Systems. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. Matthews, Ralph. 1983. The Creation of Regional Dependency. Toronto : University of Toronto Press. McAndrew, John. 1990. The Urban Process and Social Differentiation in a Philippine Village. In Datta, Satya (Ed), Third World Urbanization. Swedish Council for Research in thr Humanities and Social Sciences, Stockholm. Pp. 186-203. McGee, T.G. 1967. The Southeast Asian Cities. London: G. Bells and Son. McGee, T.G. 1971. The Urbanization Process in the Third World : Explorations in Search of a Theory. London: G. Bell and Sons, Ltd. McGee, T.G. 1989. Urbanisasi or Kotadesasi? : Evolving Patterns of Urbanization in Asia. Chapter 6, in Costa, F.J., AK. Dutt, L.J.C. Ma, and AG. Noble (Eds). 1989. Urbanization in Asia : Spatial Dimensions and Policy Issues. Honolulu : University of Hawaii Press. Pp. 93-108. McGee, T.G. 1991. The Emergence of Desakota Regions in Asia : Expanding a Hypothesis. In Ginsburg, N., B. Koppel, and T.G. McGee (Eds). 1991. Metropolis: Settlement Transition in Asia. Honolulu : University of Hawaii Press. Pp. 3-26. Mehretu, Assefa. 1989. Regional Disparities in Sub-Saharan Afiica : Structural Readjustment of Uneven Development. Boulder : Westview Press. Mehretu, Assefa, a1. Wittick, and aw. Pigozzi. 1983. Spatial Design for Basic Needs in Eastern Upper Volta. Journal of Developing Areas 17: 383-394. Mehretu, Assefa. 1983. Cities of Subsaharan Afiica. In Brunn, Stanley D. and Jack F. erliams (Eds), Cities of the World: World Regional Urban Development. New York: Harper Collin Publishers, Inc. Pp. 243-280. Mellert, R. 1985. Why We Should Feel Responsible for Future Generations. In Chiras, D.D. , Environmental Science: A Framework for Decision Making. The Benjamins/Cummings Publishing Co., Inc. l9l Mellor, John W. 1966. The Economics of Agricultural Development. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Mellor, John W. 1986. Agriculture on the Road of Industrialization. In Lewis, John P. and Kallab, Valeriana (eds), Development Strategies Reconsidered. Overseas Development Council: U.S.-Third World Policy Perspectives No. 5. New brunswick: Transaction Books. Pp. 67-90. Mellor, John W. 1988. Global Food Balances and Food Security. World Development 16(9):997-1011. Moochtar, Radinal. 1992. Key Note Address on: "Urban Growth towards the Year 2000 and Beyond”. Ministry of Public Works, Jakarta 19 November 1992. Mullen, John D. and Byron M. Roth. 1991. Decision Making: Its Logic and Practice. Maryland: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc. Murphey, Rhoads. 1966. Urbanization in Asia. Chapter 6, in Breese, G. (Ed), The City in New Developing Countries: Readings on Urbanism and Urbanization. Englewood Clifl‘s, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall Inc. Pp. 58-75. Myrdal, Gunnar. 1957. Rich Lands and Poor: The Road to World Prosperity. New York: Harper. Nasoetion, L. I. 1994. Kebijaksanaan Pertanahan Nasional dalam Mendukung Pembangunan Ekonomi : Pengalaman Masa Lalu, Tantangan dan Arah ke Masa Depan. OrasiIlmiahGuruBesarTetalemuTanah,FakultasPertanian,Institut Pertanian Bogor. Nath, V. Urbanization in India : Restrospect and Prospect. Chapter 3, in Costa, F.J., AK. Dutt, L.J.C. Ma, and AG. Noble (Eds). 1989. Urbanization in Asia : Spatial Dimensions and Policy Issues. Honolulu : University of Hawaii Press. Pp. 27-46. Naylor, Rosamond. 1992. Labor-Saving Technologies in the Javanese Rice Economy: Recent Developments and a Look into the 1990s. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, December 1992, 28(3):?1-92. Neter, John and William Wasserman. 1974. Applied Linear Statistical Models : Regression, Analysis of Variance, and Experimental Designs. Homewood, Illinois : Richard D. Irwin, Inc. Obudho, Robert A. and Waller, Peter P. 1976. Periodic Markets, Urbanization, and Regional Planning. West Port, Connecticut : Greenwood Press. I92 Okun, B. and R.W. Richardson (Eds). 1961. Studies in Economic Development. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston. Ongkosongo, Otto SR. 1979. The Oceanographic Features of the Coastal Region between Jakarta and Cirebon : Geology. In Bird, E.C.F. and A. Soegiarto (Eds). 1979. Proceeding of the Jakarta Workshop on Coastal Resources Management. Pp. 35-42. Ott, Lyman. 1988. An Introduction to Statistical Methods and Data Analysis. Third Edition. Boston: PWS-Kent Publishing Company. Phillips, Paul. 1978. Regional Disparities. Toronto : James Lorimer & Co. Pingali, P.L., P.F. Moya, and LE. Velasco. 1990. The Post-Green Revolution Blues in Asian Rice Production: the Diminished Gap Between Experiment Station and Partner Yields. Social Science Division, Internaional Rice Research Institute (IRRI), Manila, Philippines. Poot, H., A. Kuyvenhoven, and J. Jansen. 1990. Industrialization and Trade in Indonesia. Yogyakarta: Gadjah Mada University Press. Preston, D. 1975. Rural-Urban and Inter-Settlement Interaction : Theory and Analytical Structure. Area 7: 171-174. Ranis, Gustav and John C.H. Fei. 1961. A Theory of Economic Development. American Economic Review 51(4):533-565. Ranis, Gustav. 1963. Innovation, Capital Accumulation, and Economic Development. American Economic Review 53(3):283-313. Ranis, Gustav. 1964. Development of the Labor Surplus Economy: Theory and Policy. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Darwin. Reed, Robert R 1990. Patterns of Migration in Southeast Asia. Center for South and Southeast Studies, University of California at Berkeley, California. , Reissman, Leonard. 1964. The Urban Process : Cities in Industrial Societies. Illinois : Glencoe. Rondinelli, DA. 1983. Secondary Cities in Developing Countries : Policies for Diffusing Urbanization : Beverly Hills : Sage. Rondinelli, DA. 1985. Applied Methods of Regional Analysis : the Spatial Dimensions of Development Policy. Boulder, Colorado : Westview. 1: i“ 193 Rondinelli, Denis A. and Kenneth Ruddle. 1976. Urban Functions in Rural Development: An Analysis of Integrated Spatial Development Policy. Office of Urban Development, Technical Assistance Bureau, Agency for International Development, US. Department of State. Runyon, Richard P. and Audrey Haber. 1980. Fundamentals of Behavioral Statistics. Massachussetts and California : Addison-Wesley Publishing Company. Ruttan, Vernon W. 1990. Models of Agricultural Development. In Eicher, Carl K. and John M. Staatz (eds), Agricultural Development in the Third World. Second Edition. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. Pp. 89-96. Rattan, Vernon W. 1990. Sustainable Is Not Enough. Chapter 24, in Eicher, Carl K. and John M. Staatz (Eds), Agricultural Development in the Third World. Second Edition. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. Pp. 400-404. Santos, T. D. 1970. The Structure of Dependence. American Economic Review 60:231- 236. Schaik, AV. 1986. Colonial Control and Peasant Resources in Java: Agricultural Involution Reconsidered. Netherlands Geographical Studies (Nederlandse Geografische Studies) 14. Schickele, Rainer. 1954. Agricultural Policy: Farm Programs and National Welfare. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc. Schmid, A Alan. 1968. Converting Land from Rural to Urban Uses. Baltimore, Maryland: John Hopkins Press. Schultink, Gerhardus. 1992a. Evaluation of Sustainable Development Alternatives: Relevant Concepts, Resource Assessment Approaches and Comparative Spatial Indicators. Intern. J. Environmental Studies 41:203-234. Seers, Dudley. 1970. The Meaning of Development. ADC Reprint. New York: Agricultural Development Council. Sen, Amartya. 1990. Food, Economics, and Entitlements. Chapter 11, in Eicher, Carl K. and John M. Staatz (Eds), Agricultural Development in the Third World. Second Edition. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. Pp. 189-205. Sharbatoine, A. 1991. Urbanization and Regional Disparities in Post-Revolutionary Iran. Boulder, San Francisco, and Oxford : Westview Press. Sjoberg, Gideon. 1960. The Preindustrial City: Past and Present. New York: The Free Press. 194 Smith, David M. 1982. Where the Grass is Greener: Living in an Unequal World. Baltimore, Maryland: John Hopkins University Press. Soegijoko, Sugijanto. 1992. Regional and Urban Development in Indonesia: Achievement and Options for the Future. Keynote Paper in the Conference of "Urban Growth towards the Year 2000 and Beyond”. Jakarta, 19 November 1992. Pp. 7-28. Soemarwoto, O., I. Soemarwoto, H. Salim, O.S. Abdoellah, C. Asdak, R. Muslihudin, S. Astuti, and T. Herawati. 1991. Sustainable Development of West Java. Institute of Ecology, Padjadjaran University, Bandung, Indonesia. Soemarwoto, Otto. 1992. Questions of Sustainability in Urban Development. Paper Presented in the Conference of "Urban Growth towards the Year 2000 and Beyond". Jakarta, 19 November 1992. Pp. 1.28-1.44. Southall, AS. 1977. Small Urban Centers in Rural Development in Afiica. Research Proposal, Mimeo, University of VVlsconsin, Madison. Southall, Aidan. 1979. Introduction. In Southall, Aidan, Small Urban Centers in Rural Development in Afiica. Afiican Studies Program, University of Wisconsin, Madison, Msconsin. Pp. 1-20. Sovani, NV. 1964. The Analysis of Over-Urbanization. Economic Development and Cultural Change 12(12): 1 13-122. Stevens, Robert D. and Cathy L. Jabara. 1988. Agricultural Development Principles: Economic Theory and Empirical Evidence. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. Stohr, Walter B. 1981. Development from Below : The Bottom-Up and Periphery- Inward Development Paradigm. Chapter 2, in Stohr, Walter B. and D.R.F. Taylor. 1981. Development fi'om Above or Below? : The Dialectics of Regional Planning in Developing Countries. New York : John Wiley and Sons. Pp. 39-72. Streeten, Paul. 1984. Basic Needs: Some Unsettled Questions. Working Paper No. 56, Michigan State University. Sutton, Keith. 1989. The Role of Urban Bias in Perpetuating Rural-Urban Disparities in the Maghreb. In Potter RB. and T. Unwin (Eds). 1989. The Geography of Urban- Rural Interaction in Developing Countries. London : Routledge. Pp. 68-108. I95 Tabor, Steven R. 1992. Agriculture in Transition. Chapter 6 in Booth, Anne (Ed), The Oil Boom and Alter: Indonesian Economic Policy and Performance in the Soeharto Era. New York: Oxford University Press. Pp. 161-203. Tarrant, J. et all. 1987. Natural Resources and Environmental Management in Indonesia. Jakarta, Indonesia: United States Agency for International Development. Thomas, RW. and RJ. Hugget. 1980. Modelling in Geography: A Mathematical Approach. Totowa, New Jersey: Barnes & Noble Books. Thrall, Grant Ian. 1987. Land Use and Urban Form : The Consumption Theory of Land Rent. New York : Methuen. Tirnmer, C. Peter. 1990. The Agricultural Transformation. Chapter 2, in Eicher, Carl K. and John M. Staatz (Eds), Agricultural Development in the Third World. Second Edition. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. Pp. 47-69. Toner, William. 1979. Local Programs to Save Farms and Farmlands. In Schnepf, Max (Ed), Farmland, Food, and the Future. Iowa: Soil Conservation Society of America. Pp. 189-202. UNCED. 1987. Our Common Future. Oxford University Press. Unwin, Tim. 1989. Urban-Rural Interaction in Developing Countries: A Theoretical Perspective. Chapter 1, in Potter, RB. and Tim Unwin (Eds), The Geography of Urban-Rural Interaction in Developing Countries. London : Routledge. Pp. 1 1-3 2. Wilber, Charles K. and James H. Weaver, 1979. Patterns of Dependency: Income Distribution and the History of Underdevelopment. In Wilber, Charles K. (Ed), The Political Economy of Development and Underdevelopment. New York: Random House. Pp. 114-130. Williams, Frederick. 1986. Reasoning with Statistics. Third Edition. New York : Holt, Rinehart, and Winston. Williams, Jack F., Stanley D. Brunn, and Joe T. Darden. 1983. World Urban Development. In Brunn, Stanley D. and Jack F. Williams (Eds), Cities of the World: World Regional Urban Development. New York: Harper Collin Publishers, Inc. Pp. 3-42. Winoto, Joyo. 1985. ”Pengaruh Permukaan Air Tanah Terhadap Proses Pembentukan Tanah Sawah" (Impacts of Water Tables on the Genesis of Paddy Lands). Department of Soil Sciences, Bogor Agricultural University. 196 World Bank. 1990. Indonesia: Strategy for a Sustained Reduction in Poverty. A World Bank Country Study. Washington, D.C.:The World Bank. World Bank. 1994. World Development Report : Infrastructure for Development. The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank, Washington, DC. Wrigley, N. (Ed). 1979. Statistical Applications in the Spatial Sciences. Brondesbury Park, London: Page Bros (Norwich) Limited. Zain, 2.8. M. 1987. Pattern of Spatial Development and Regional Inequalities in Peninsular Malaysia. A Dissertation. Urban and Regional Planning Program, College of Social Science, Michigan State University.