7.5x ... r J 5.23;. In ‘* " w‘ 42: .— "4‘. _V< A 'f. Egan. . "a. :5; '13" ‘ x' a}! ‘2‘;- 4‘ s v 4 Wk 32W 2%“ . x " 4% mg??? m r 4 - gg'efiMt’xfif '1! .1. Q‘ 4 .113 I - | . "fr”ii‘ “ .l V * ‘ ~12- 13m ~32 L 1‘ "1:67 ‘1'},‘1'5Vfi: ’ 3 on Q15 . ‘5'“0” 15$"? Ii “ "évfivhfi’f if" '1‘ Ii'f'fi'f Lt V' [d ’ ‘31“ ’ ' n ‘u 311% 13‘9“! ‘ '4 - "57'3“ 1'26 4; 'v‘ 9;! . \55 ”it“? ._v 4" ‘V: j: fl“. ,' x4 ' ‘ $24" A.- h “£52 "f. @316“ ”33 Q. ~ 1: . “,1 . 53%;. 16 '7‘ u v- . I L ‘ l" M- ’f "5 ‘2’ | , 1|‘y ."N'H “ 9 - A J: é Ir: 3"? , ,5’E‘58. :3“ '. . '- .f-f 1 . “32:257er s. v . 5 L m?"- ‘ '1‘»! figfifiW ' ‘ 554? V 1-,. o .J I ‘ . .33; 4' f. . W I l‘ ,‘I "- I; ‘7 \iiiiiiiiii ii i; ii iii ,5 ‘_ LIBRARY ( " “1, Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Explanations and Predictions of Political Success of the Heads of Government since 1945 presented by Meeyoung Ju has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D degree in Political Science Major professor Date November 21 ,1994 MS U is an Affirmatiw Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 -———r~ - _ ‘ -h m- me: It RETURN BOX to man than chockout from your Me To AVOID FINES return on or baton data duo. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE MSU to An Mandi“ Action/Equal Opportunity Institmion amps-m EXPLANATIONS AND PREDICTIONS OF POLITICAL SUCCESS OF THE HEADS OF GOVERNMENT SINCE 1945 By Meeyoung In A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science 1 994 real power in decision-making. Mostly, they were the presidents, the prime ministers, and the general secretaries over 137 countries from 1945 to 1991 including leaders who were in office in 1991. A two-equation model, which is composed of a probit selection equation as well as an ordered probit substantive equation, is used to estimate its parameters. The results suggest that the model has not only explanatory but also predictive value. In comparison of the reduced models (i.e., social background model, career background model, and institutional attributes model), the results reveal that the career background model best explains political survival. However, the institutional attributes model accounts for the strength of survival. Nonetheless, the overall goodness-of-fit of the interaction model is better than others. And, the regional models contribute different explanations to political survival. Finally, the descriptive analysis of personal backgrounds shows the similarities and differences of leaders using the variables that can not be included in the empirical models because of high percentages of missing data. To my mother and late father, With Love and Gratitude iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I wish to thank all my committee members, Brian Silver, Nick van de Walle, Larry Heimann, and Jerry Weinberger, for their guidance, advice, and support. I also would like to thank family members who have been very caring, and supportive without losing their patience. Without friends, my days in America could have not been easier and happier. To all of my friends, whom I have known and met in America, I must express a real big "Thanksl". TABLE OF CONTENTS INTRODUCTION ............................................. 1 CHAPTER I Review of the Literature on Political Leadership ............ 8 Classical Views on Political Leadership .................. 8 Empirical Views on Political Leadership ................. 10 A. Great Man Theory .............................. 13 B. Social Background Theory ........................ 15 C. Trait and Personality Theory ....................... 17 D. Situation Theory ............................... 20 E. Interaction Theory .............................. 23 CHAPTER 11 Theoretical Perspectives of Political Success .............. 29 A. The Concept of Political Success .................... 33 B. The Concept of Head of Government ................. 39 C. Theoretical Model .............................. 45 CHAPTER III Theoretical Propositions ............................ 52 . A. Do Social Backgrounds of Leaders Really Matter for Their Political Survival? .............................. 56 B. Do Career Backgrounds of Leaders Have Influence on Their Political Survival? .............................. 58 C. How Do the Institutional Attributes Influence Political Survival? .................................... 63 CHAPTER IV Operationalization and Methodology .................... 76 A. Data Collection and Operationalization ................ 76 Data Collection ................................ 77 Operationalization .............................. 82 B. Methodology .................................. 85 Statistical Analysis .............................. 85 Descriptive Analysis ............................ 96 CHAPTER V Presentation and Discussion of Results .................. 99 A. Statistical Analyses of the Two—Equation Model ........ 101 Analysis of Social Backgrounds ................... 101 vi Analysis of Career Backgrounds ................... 104 Analysis of Institutional Attributes .................. 107 Analysis of Interaction Model ..................... 114 B. Analysis of Regional Models ..................... 123 CHAPTER VI Descriptive Analysis of Personal Backgrounds ............ 133 A. Comparisons by Region ......................... 135 B. Comparisons by Duration ........................ 145 C. Comparisons by Type of Head of Government ......... 154 D. Comparisons by Number of Entry .................. 159 CHAPTER VII CONCLUSION ................................. 163 APPENDICES ....................... ' ....................... 178 APPENDIX A. Data Sources and Data Codebook ......... 180 APPENDIX B. Hazard Rate (Life Tables) .............. 188 APPENDIX C. Ordinary Least Squares Estimation ........ 189 LIST OF REFERENCES ...................................... 190 vii LIST OF TABLES Table l Dummy Variables ..................................... 90 Table 2 Coefficient Estimates for Social Background Variables .......... 103 Table 3 Coefficient Estimates for Career Background Variables .......... 106 Table 4 Coefficient Estimates for. Institutional Attributes ............... 109 Table 5 Success of Prediction in Political Survival ................... 113 Table 6 Coefficient Estimates for Interaction Model .................. 116 Table 7 Success of Prediction in Interaction Model .................. 120 Table 8 Goodness-of-F it of Selection Equations ..................... 122 Table 9 Significant Variables in Regional Models ................... 124 Table 10 Goodness-of-F it of Regional Models ....................... 130 Table 11 Homogeneity Scores in Social Backgrounds, Career Backgrounds, and Skills and Personality By Region ...................... 136 Table 12 Homogeneity Scores in Social Backgrounds, Career Backgrounds, and Skills and Personality By Duration ..................... 146 Table 13 Homogeneity Scores in Social Backgrounds, Career Backgrounds, and Skills and Personality By Type of Head of Government and Number of Entry .................................... 156 Table 14 Ordinary Least Squares Estimation ........................ 189 viii Figure 1 Figure 2 Figure 3 Figure 4 Figure 5 Figure 6 Figure 7 Figure 8 Figure 9 Figure 10 Figure 11 Figure 12 Figure 13 Figure 14 Figure 15 Figure 16 Figure 17 LIST OF FIGURES Political Success .................................... 51 Distribution of Duration (Percentage) ...................... 78 Cases Excluded from the Sample ......................... 78 Age Groups by Region ............................... 137 Educational Level by Region ........................... 137 Majors by Region .................................. 140 Foreign, Military, Prison/Exile, and P01. Activity Experiences by Region ....................................... 140 Political Experiences by Region ......................... 142 Political Skills by Region ............................. 142 Age Groups by Duration .............................. 147 Entry Mode by Duration .............................. 147 Foreign, Military, Prison/Exile, and P01. Activity Experiences by Duration ....................................... 149 Political Experiences by Duration ...................... . 149 Political Skills by Duration . . .. ......................... 151 Party System by Duration ............................. 151 Age Groups by Type of Head of Government ............... 155 Political Skills by Type of Head of Government ............. 157 ix Figure 18 Figure 19 Figure 20 Figure 21 Figure 22 Foreign, Military, Prison/Exile, and P01. Activity Experiences by Number of Entry ................................. 159 Political Experiences by Number of Entry .................. 160 Personality by Number of Entry ........................ 160 Hazard Rate of Total Sample (N=984) .................... 188 Hazard Rate of Censored Sample (N=882) ................. 188 INTRODUCTION Research on political leadership has drawn upon psychological, sociocultural, historical, politicoeconomic, and philosophical concerns. Even though it has been discussed with interrelated conceptual themes (i.e., leaders, heroes, elites, exercise of influence, power, authority and control, legitimacy, etc.) and with a multidisciplinary perspective, leadership has eluded any easy and simple theoretical explanations. Assessing and measuring political leadership is very complex and difficult since almost any propositions concerning it present a series of contradictions, tensions, and antinomies. An enormous variety of new conceptual definitions, contending theories, and incongruent standards of measurement appears to have complicated rather than simplified the comparative analysis of political leadership (Edinger, 1975). Whether the study of political leadership is productive depends on the definition of political leadership and the models which the investigators choose to employ. Political leadership is a timeless and universal phenomenon, and all societies at all times have their leaders. Political leaders come in many forms, with many styles and diverse qualities, and at different times. There are some quiet leaders and some famous or notorious leaders one can hear about even in neighboring countries. Some find their strength in eloquence, some in judgment, and some in courage. Leaders seem to be good or bad, heroes or villains; but leaders seem also to be more or less 2 successful, more or less effective (Blondel, 1980, p.277). When we say ’here is an effective leader, a wise statesman, a just ruler’, or, on the other hand, call a leader a tyrant, an opportunist, or a fraud, we make comparisons between what we see in a leader and what we expect of one (Edinger, 1976). Definitely, there is a need for a systematic and empirical analysis of the achievements of leaders. For example, we can find an analysis that so far has only been in a partial manner about some revolutionary leaders (Rajai and Phillips, 1979 & 1983). When we evaluate the fitness of candidates for certain positions, judge the performance of political leaders, or compare our political leaders with those who aspire to displace them or rule other people, we usually compare and generalize the characteristics or the issues that they hold and the situation in which they are found. It will be worth comparing present political leaders against the leaders of bygone days, between different countries at different time periods, and generalizing about the features that make them successful or unsuccessful. Although psychological aspects of political success are difficult to analyze and are just beginning to be examined systematically in the context of individual leaders, it is possible to frnd the broader social backgrounds and career profiles of political leaders, political and social environments, as well as the characteristics of the rise or fall of leaders that have been easily documented. In a simple and highly abstract model, a set of factors determines an outcome in terms of winning-losing or success-failure. Questions of leader’s success and failure are both empirically and nonnatively important; yet scholarly writing in that area suffers from a lack of clear criteria (Sinclair, 1993). Political leadership of society, whether democratic, autocratic, or monarchic, at least initially derives its power and authority 3 from the support or acquiescence of one or more dominant segments of society. If political success is related to the concept of ’power’, we can say ’tenure is power’. Some political leaders are more successful than others, while some are not successful at all. Typologizing leaders on the theoretically important dimensions of social backgrounds, career backgrounds, personality, and environmental differences, would permit explanation and prediction of leaders’ performance in office on the basis of their durations of office. Assuredly, the best leaders - perhaps the only good ones - are those who view their task as that of a moment, although perhaps a major moment, in their country’s history (Blondel, 1987, p.47). However, in this dissertation, the main focus is not on whether a leader is good or bad, but on what makes him successful or unsuccessful based on his duration ‘in office. Although there have been several arguments for explaining political success in different ways, political success based on a leader’s performance might be indicated by how long the leaders stay in offices as a head of the government. In this study, political success is viewed as political survival. The longer political leaders stay in their offices, the more successful they are, regardless of whether they exit peacefully and constitutionally or forcedly and nonconstitutionally. Some leaders with a long duration of office got out of their offices in such constitutional ways as retirement, resignation, defeat in election, or natural death.1 At the same time, some ’ The examples of natural death are Enver Hoxha in Albania (4] yrs), Mao Tse-Tung in China (27 yrs), Sekou Toure in Guinea (24 yrs), Seretse Khama in Botswana (13 yrs), Gamel Nasser in Egypt (15 yrs), Forbes Bumham in Guyana (14 yrs), Jomo Kenyatta in Kenya (14 yrs), Jawaharlal Nehru in India (16 yrs), Francisco Franco y Bustelo in Spain (34 yrs), Sékou Toure in Guinea (24 yrs), Chang Kai- sek in Taiwan (25 yrs) Eric Williams in Trininad and Tobago (19 yrs), etc. And, the examples of other 4 leaders who stayed in office for a long period of time were deposed by coup d’etat, assassinated, or expelled by force.2 In the latter case, can we consider them successful leaders? How about the leaders with a short stay and a peaceful exit? Nonetheless, considering that ’duration of office’ is an element of personal position and that ’disposal of leader’ is an indicator of the strength of personal position, the subject of political survival is more related to the duration of office as a general concept. Even though it is possible to expand on several questions, this study will focus on why some leaders stay in office longer than others. Measuring success or failure is not easy; however, it is possible to see whether a leader stayed long enough to achieve satisfaction as an office holder. Whether or not a leader advances his goals is a solid initial basis for gauging degree of success or failure. In.order to accomplish what he sets out to achieve, he needs to maintain his office as long as possible. The polity is managed for survival of the leadership rather than for equitable development of the polity. To hold an office longer as a top executive, political stability should be guaranteed. Even though durability is an elusive concept since relatively frequent changes of chief executive may conceal a good deal of continuity in the parties and peaceful exit after long duration of office are Todor Zhivkov in Bulgaria (36 yrs), Wladyslaw Gomulka in Poland (14 yrs), Robert Menzies in Australia (16 yrs), Mathieu Kerekou in Benin (19 yrs), Ne win in Burma (19 yrs), Konrad Adenauer in West Germany (14 yrs), Tage Erlander in Sweden (23 yrs), Augusto Pinochet Ugarte in Chile (15 yrs), Mathieu Kerekou in Benin (19 yrs), Ahmadou Ahidjo in Cameroon (22 yrs), Yumjagiyn Tsedenbal in Mogolia (32 yrs), Anker Jorgensen in Denmark (17 yrs), Urho Kekkonen in Finland (16 yrs), Walter Ulbricht (21 yrs) and Erich Honecker (18 yrs) in East Germany, etc. 2 The examples of forceful exit are Janos Kadar in Hungary (33 yrs), Ahmed Sukarno in Indonesia (16 yrs), Norodom Sihanouk in Kampuchea (16 yrs), Moktar Ould Daddah in Mauritania (17 yrs), Alfredo Stroessner in Paraguay (35 yrs), Feminad Marcos in Philippines (20 yrs), Jaaffar el-Nemery in Sudan (16 yrs), Leabua Jonathan in Lethoso (19 yrs), Moussa Traoré in Mali (23 yrs), Nicolae Ceausescu in Romania (26 yrs), Siyad Barreh in Somalia (22 yrs), etc. Anastasio Somoza Garcia in Nicaragua (19 yrs), Park Junghee in South Korea (17 yrs), Ngarta Tombala in Chad (14 yrs), Anwar el- Sadat in Egypt (11 yrs), etc. were assassinated. 5 personnel in power, durability of political leaders can be an indicator of political stability. Even if we can not study political leadership and political leaders in a full sense of the word, we can limit the scope to the people in certain positions and analyze them. The sample for this dissertation will be the heads of national governments from the end of World War II to the end of 1991. While official titles differ from country to country, a head of government may be defined as a person who really has been or is in power in each country. Top executives are almost always interested in maintaining ofiices and the power of the purse has long been crucial in their search for security. The security of top executives is generally proportional to the length of time they hold office; newly elected leaders are the most insecure. From 1945 to 1991, more than 1,000 individuals have been at the top at their countries. Of course, many others sought but did not achieve such a post. Some stayed in office for longer periods than others and held a position more than once. This study will include relatively large numbers of comparable cases (997 cases) which lend themselves not only to making qualitative statements but also to quantitative statements, statistical analyses, and empirical generalizations. Thus, finding a good method of classifying qualitative data for this study is very important. Modeling with the variables that imply certain characteristics, i.e., duration data, high percentage of missing data, and several dummies, should be done with care. This dissertation will focus on the comparative analysis of political leadership across countries, combining the basic themes and questions that delineate different aspects of political success or survival. There have been a range of philosophical 6 opinions on political success examined by philosophers qua philosophers, over time, and in the West vs. the East. Philosophers mainly deal with depicting the nature of an ideal leader. Some philosophers focus on the nature of human beings from which the concept of political. leadership derived. These fundamental philosophical perspectives on the idea of political leadership would provide the requisite attributes that an ideal leader should have. However, I Will review more recent literature on political leadership success based on more theoretical or empirical speculation. It will explicate the images that we really see in a leader. Most of the prevailing studies of political leadership are analyzed in a descriptive way. Through descriptive analyses, it is possible to identify several important factors that make leaders different or similar by comparison. Basically, examining those factors - such as social background, career background, personality and skills, and contexts - will allow us to do predictive and causal analyses on political success or survival. The main purpose of this study, however, is to determine whether the subject of political leadership survival as indicated by political success can be studied in empirical and comparative .ways. Furthermore, introducing a quantitative method with qualitative data will test how personal qualities, that is, individual differences on social and career backgrounds, and institutional differences are related to political success or survival. Thus, this study will put emphases on models that will test: (1) What are important factors that determine political success?; (2) ‘Do social background factors influence political success?; (3) Does political success depend on career background variables?; (4) Do situational or institutional factors have effects on political success?; 7 (5) What subset of factors among the above can best explain political success?; (6) If a leader is successful, what makes him or her more successful or less successful than others?; (7) Do qualities of political leaders change across the different regions or with the systematic differences in politics?; and, (8) Can we expect some individuals with some qualities would be successful political leaders in the future? CHAPTER I Review of the Literature on Political Leadership In this part, I will review more recently-explored literature that focuses on theoretical or empirical aspects of political leadership instead of any specific deep philosophical reviews. Although the principles of proper political leadership are based on generalized assumptions about the nature of man, society, sovereignty, and authority emphasized by several political philosophers, those normative views focus on a question of ’who should govern’. In order to look at ’who in fact did rule’, it is more appropriate to focus on empirical views that discern those characteristics of politicians that would suggest explanations and predictions of their effectiveness or success. Classical Views on Political Leadership Political philosophers used to be interested in ethics: What makes good leadership - for the led as well as for the leader himself? They outlined what some would label an ideal of leadership, although it is presented as a model to be emulated by ordinary people functioning in the routine circumstances of daily life. Western philosophers have never been silent on the question of leadership. From Plato’s philosopher-king to Machiavelli’s prince, from Hobbes’ sovereignty to Nietzsche’s Ubermensch, philosophy has said its piece on the nature of the ideal leader (Grob, 1984, p.263). Especially, in ’T he Prince’ and ’The Discourses’, Machiavelli devotes the core of his analysis to the study of the way in which rulers should behave. His analysis is 9 ' devoted to the elaboration of technical and tactical moves designed to ensure the success of rulers and their maintenance or expansion in office. The substantial purpose of leadership is subordinated to the problems of the stability of ruler in office since, to be certain, stability is an overriding goal in politics. Montesquieu had more interest in government that is sensitive to sociological and ecological differences of every country. Those ecological conditioning factors provided certain settings that condition political systems to be constituted properly. To him, whether it is a natural property of small states to be governed as republics, of middle ones to be governed by monarchs, or of large empires to be ruled by despots, it follows that in order to preserve the principles of any established government it is necessary to maintain the existing size of the state; and that the nature of the state will change to the extent that the state constructs or extends its limits (Corrinthers, 1977). Also, Saint-Simon emphasizes the men who are most fitted to manage the affairs of the nation and possess the most eminent, varied, and most positively useful ability for managing national interests and maintaining public order. Later, Max Weber contributed many things to the study of political leadership, introducing three types of legitimate rule or authority. He tended to regard nonlegitimate ’power authorities’ as unstable and short-lived. He was not much concerned with the specific ways in which leaders achieve power, how long they are in office or how they exit. Only to the extent that duration and exit mode may affect the legitimacy of the whole system are these problems examined especially in the context of charismatic authority. Eastern philosophers also have been interested in political leadership. Not only 10 the Confucian philosophers such as Confucius and Mencius but also the Taoist, Lao Tze, proclaimed that government officials should be responsible for establishing virtue throughout the realism. Confucianism urges rule through the ’power of virtue’ and moral suasion, whereas the Taoist image of leadership indicates nonleadership such that ’the greatest conqueror wins without joining issue’ (Lao Tze, 1961). The idea of ’superior-man’ is based on the harmony of a perfect individual and a well-ordered society to bring peace to the people. While the Confucian tradition of rule has been regarded as the rule by men, not by law, the legalist image of leadership by the manipulation of rewards and punishments was introduced by Han F ei Tzu. Recently, Mao’s political moralism (pragmatism) was rooted in ancient Chinese tradition and he, in fact, was not the first political thinker to view the moral reform of citizens as the province of political leadership. On the basis of his virtuocratic and meritocratic values, the military arts were not highly valued. Soldiers ofien stepped in to impose their will on a disorderly or corrupt political scene, but no cult of the warrior ever emerged to supplant the civilian values of Confucianism. Empirical Views on Political Leadership Modern developments - to the detriment of ethical and philosophical considerations - such as various theories, research methods, and psychological implications have had the effect of emphasizing the quasi-scientific aspect of political leadership (Hodgkinson, 1983). The focus of interests in political leadership has been shifted from theory to research. Over the past decades, political leadership or political ll elites have been considered as an important issue in the area of political science. As Plato’s The Republic or Gorgias, Machiavelli’s The Prince, and even Confucius’ The Analects mainly deal with what is an ideal leadership, these recorded classics could provide some theoretical explanations. However, we need some empirical research on action-relevant understanding, theoretical elaboration, comparison, experimentation and prediction. Even though we can set up an image of ideal political leadership, it is impossible to have those ideal leaders. We just select somebody as a likely potential winner, or preferable to others as our leaders. Nonetheless, it is not certain that leaders with ideal qualities would survive long in a very changing situation. Research on how political figures are perceived by the public has proceeded in several aspects; citizens judge leaders, such as presidents and prime ministers, by the party they represent or with which they are affiliated (Campbell, et al., 1960). The public conceptions of political leaders are associated with such diverse elements as leaders announcing positions or policies they promote or oppose (Weisberg and Rusk, 1970; Markus and Converse, 1979) or the consequences of such policies (Hibbs, et al., 1982). Also, some researchers put emphases on personal qualities such as honesty, intelligence, and integrity; or competence of the leaders such as past political experience as important characters in leader and candidate experience. More recent leadership theory tends to be regarded as a subdivision of psychology or sociology rather than of philosophy. Burns (1979) summarized such a trend as follows: 12 Historians and biographers focus on the unique person with more or less idiosyncratic qualities and traits confronting particular sets of problems and situations over time. In a meanwhile, psychologists scrutinize generic factors, early intrafamily relationships widening arcs of personal interaction, changing constellations of attitudes and motivations, whereas sociologist view the developing personality as it moves through a series of social contexts - family, school, neighborhood, workplace. Political Scientists emphasize the social and political institutions impinging on developing leaders, changes in political leaders as they learn from their experience, the eventual impact of leadership on policy and on history (p.26). The sequence of explanatory research, for instance, has been from maxims or rules of thumb through trait theory, to factor analytic trait theory (yielding the classical two dimensions of task orientation and person orientation), to situational qualifications, to interactive considerations (task plus leader, followers plus interactions), to the latter-day refined maxims of path-goal analysis, and to the current complexities of dynamic models (Rustow, 1967; Hodgkinson, 1983). Also, political scientists have proceeded far beyond Lasswell’s generalizations and typologies in exploring the psychological dimensions of their subject (Rustow, 1966, p.687). A number of biographies combined political and psychological analysis with careful attention to the canons of historical evidence (Neustadt, 1960; Edinger, 1965). Even though specific studies of political success have not been done by many scholars, there has been quite a few works closely related to this theme. If a complete answer to the question about what makes successful leadership is beyond the sc0pe of most studies, a partial response may nevertheless be assayed. They are basically divided into two broad categories that focus on individual political leaders and institutional processes and outcomes. The first category is primarily based on individual 13 qualities such as social backgrounds and career backgrounds. The second deals with the analyses of the performance of political leaders in the aspect of political stability and political development. A. Great-Man Theory For a modern analysis of individual leaders, a parent of our modern approach to political leadership is the great-man theory discussed by Thomas Carlyle (1775- 1881). According to him, the history of the world is the Biography of Great Men. As German historians saw in the human past the ever-changing manifestations of timeless national genius, Carlyle’s hero worship was influenced by them. As one of the conservative theorists, Carlyle (1966) viewed democracy as the everlasting privilege of the foolish to be governed by the wise and to be guided in the right path by those who know better than they do. His great-man resembles Plato’s philosopher-king in some respects as the belief that political rule should be exercised by the man of exceptional wisdom and ability. However, a heroic leader is an indispensable agent of historical evolution and progress; his distinctive quality is the capacity for bold and audacious action based upon an initiative, rather than a philosophical grasp of historical reality. Meanwhile, his idea is close to the spirit and tradition of Machiavelli in the sense that the hero must be immersed in the equivocation and compromise of actual life. Consequently, he provides a needed emphasis on the role and importance of superior individuals in politics. He says sincerity - a deep, great, and genuine sincerity - is the first characteristic of all men in any way heroic. 14 Most philosophical reviews on political leadership have focused on the theme similar to the great-man theory. However, the ’great-man theory’ can not be easily proved in an empirical way. As an example, if Socrates’ maxim "know thyself" is fundamental to leadership, the most important characteristic of leaders is that they must understand themselves before they can work on others. It seems to be a test for self-realization in leaders themselves. Whereas the ’great—man theory’ asserts that leaders are born and not made, most empirical studies emphasize that leadership is almost accidental, or at least that most leaders emerge from circumstances which normally do not create them. The construction of leadership would span time, cultures, and circumstances. ’Great men’ do make history, and the cause of real intended social change can be tracked back to the purposes and decisions of the most visible actors on the political stage. Carlyle’s heroes, Nietzsche’s great blond beast, Hegel’s evoker and carrier of the spirit of the times3, and Sidney Hook’s event-making man4 are the good examples for this theory. Basically, leadership is viewed typically in terms of the great man who shapes for a long period the destinies of mankind. The great-man theory has influenced some scholars (Morgenthau and. Hein, .1983) in the field of political leadership. The question, ’what is greatness in any man 3 Hegel (1952, p.295) asserted: " The great man of the age is one who can put into words the will of his age, and tell its age what its will is, and accomplish it. What he does is the heart and essence of his age; he actualizes his age." " Hook (l986)’s theory on political leadership is similar to Carlyle’s great-man theory. However, Hook named it ’the event-making man’ in history. ’The event-making man’ is an eventful man whose actions are consequences of outstanding capacities of intelligence, will, and character rather than of accidents of position. In a meanwhile, the eventful man in history is any man whose actions influenced subsequent developments along a quite different course than would have been followed if these actions had not been taken. 15 and more particularly what is greatness in a statesman?’ is one of their inquiries. The great man is the one who at least approaches perfection in certain qualities of mind, character, and action that illuminate the very nature of man. Those who become leaders do so by virtue of their possession in superior degree of certain personal traits - such as stamina, decisiveness, composure - which make it their fate to reach positions of leadership in their organizations or societies (Tucker, 1977). According to this theory, the characteristics of social backgrounds and attitudes might be introduced and explained as good criteria for the great-man. B. Social Background Theory The major reason for focusing on the social antecedents of leaders is an implicit assumption that if we know who they are, and were, and how they came to be leaders, then we already have a reliable guide to what they believe and do. According to the researchers on this theory, social origins are important, justifying their focus on arguing that social background is a useful indicator of the characteristics of a political leader (Crewe, 1974). Also, background data on the social and career characteristics of political leaders provide no infallible guide to either their attitudinal patterns or policy preferences. Biographical analysis of these characteristics can reveal much information about the nature of the political system since hypotheses concerning the functional relationship between the requirement of the political system and the social and career attributes of the political leaders (Waller, 1976, p.155). To see what kind of man becomes a political leader, it is necessary to examine the existing theories and hypotheses conceming the social backgrounds of political l6 leaders. Social background theory is based on the question: Does the political leader’s socio-economic status and previous life experience make any difference in the type of head of government, leadership characteristics (e.g., charisma or non-charisma), and the type of recruitment mechanism? In turn, the following questions are generated: (1) How can the study of social backgrounds and career patterns of political leaders contribute to an understanding of why recruitment arrangements function as they do?; (2) From what social positions are political leaders recruited?; (3) What are the interrelationships between their characteristics and political change or revolution?; (4) What are the effects of the characteristics of political leaders on the conduct of government? In fact, who becomes a political leader is not just decided by elections, primaries, and voting but, rather, is also the result of a continual sitting and sorting of the citizens who enter the quest for political power. Careful research and imaginative theorizing about trends in the social backgrounds of political leaders may supply some new insight into the phenomena of social and political change. In other words, changes of the trends in their social backgrounds may be an indication of overall social, economic, and political change. The historians, biographers, and journalists who have gathered most of the data on social backgrounds of political leaders have overlooked the universal for the unique, the general for the specific. However, what is needed to obtain a new understanding of political leaders is an approach that emphasizes the similarities rather than the differences between them. As Rustow (1967, p.684) mentioned, political writers sought to catalogue in their ’mirrors for princes’ the virtues of the ideal ruler and the principles 17 that must guide his conduct. These ideas are less normative and more empirical than those of earlier theorists and are, in turn, the basis for more recent research in this general tradition. Even though some researchers reject social background analyses, others (Rustow, 1966; Edinger and Searing, 1967; Farrell, 1970; Beck et al., 1973; Camp, 1979, 1980) are interested in a social background approach. Despite the masses of accumulated data and radical changes in the way in which data are collected and presented, one finds rather few general relationships between social facts and political behavior emerging from these studies. Rustow (1966) agreed that the study of the ruler’s social background is only a supplement, not a substitute, for the study of their performance in office - and of the effect of that performance on the recruitment of future rulers. Beck et a1. (1973) and Farrell (1970) examined personal backgrounds and educational or career characteristics of the individual leaders in communist countries. Especially, Lane (1988), recently, analyzed the ’circular flow of power’ in USSR based on social backgrounds. Camp (1979) tried to compare women political leaders with male political leaders using similar background data on recruitment and career patterns. C. Trait and Personality Theory Over the years, a group of social psychologists has tried to ascertain by experimental methods what are the individual traits of character associated with leadership (Truman, 1951; Gibbs, 1954; Erickson, 1958; Verba, 1961). Harold Lasswell was the first political scientist to introduce psychological explanations to political 18 science. He attempted to show that there are natural leaders especially equipped by personality or skill to perform important political roles. Political leaders are characterized by the possession of special personalities and skills, and an individual becomes a political leader at least in part because of certain personal qualities or traits. The same skills and traits are required to be a leader in all situations and circumstances. Burns (1977) backs up Lasswell’s view explaining political leadership with more specific psychological factors, such as wants, needs, aspirations and expectations. According to Dahl (1969), political skill is generally thought to be of critical importance in explaining the power of different leaders. However, despite many attempts at analysis, from Machiavelli to the present day, political skill has remained among the more elusive aspects of power. The trait or personality theory asserts that a prominent political figure is analyzed in order to discover the significance of his main political role in the context of his whole personality system (Lasswell, 1965; Barber, 1965; George, 1968; Greenstein, 1985). Erickson (1964) claims that the success of leaders depends on a match between their own personal characteristics and historically conditioned characteristics of their political followers. In a word, for this study, there are several personality and skills factors that may account for the personal greatness of political leaders. Foti et al. (1982) assert that different leadership labels imply different characteristics. Mainly based on perceptional theory (i.e., social information processing), prototypical ratings generated through several items explain which of a series of trait and behavioral descriptions of national political leaders would covary with 19 their effectiveness. Suedfeld and Rank (1976) showed that the political fate of revolutionary leaders, that is, success or failure, was decided by the skill in adapting to the information-processing demands of the environment. For an example, long-term success for a leader would be associated with low conceptual complexity (single- minded) during the revolutionary phase, followed by a change to high complexity (graduated, flexible, and integrated) during the poststruggle phrase. Leadership is a traitlike quality possessed by certain individuals, arguing instead that leadership is an attribution made by perceivers that explains outcomes or characteristics associated with actors (Merriam, 1967; Calder, 1977; Lord & Rush, 1980; Pfeffer, 1977; Foti, Fraser and Lord, 1982). Some have advanced and developed the concept of a particular political personality or character type in pursuit of power over other values (Lasswell, 1948; Lane, 1961; Seligman, 1950). Political leadership focuses on what Easton (1953) has called the authoritative allocation of values in a community and involves both the attempt to exercise and the actual exercise of power to make policy-choices between alternative courses of action affecting this allocation of values. Especially in case of the revolutionaries, most researchers emphasize psychological explanations. Lasswell’s paradigm for power-seeking explains a contemporary mechanism for feelings of inadequacy and low self-esteem, a private need that is located on public objects and rationalized in terms of the public interest. Burns (1979) focuses on the analysis of the interrelationships of persons on-the basis only of power. Based on this theory, most research deals with political styles according to which the leaders are categorized. 20 Although both the Freudian perspectives, which emphasize a leader as a father figure, and the idea of the leader as a person who voices the ideological concerns of his followers, are persuasive, there is relatively little social psychological research that bears on either hypothesis. Childhood development, socialization, and ego psychology are the related areas with trait theory. ’Power seeker’ is a person who pursues power as a means of compensation against deprivation. Once in power, every leader wants to stay in office as long as possible, attempting recasting political institutions, reinterpreting and expanding the functions of existing political roles or creating new ones which fit their needs, political styles and aspirations (George, 1968). Most people intuitively expect leaders to have some personality traits or attributes which set them apart. However, ’trait theory’ or ’personality theory’ could be attacked for several reasons. According to Greenstein (1986, p.36), personality characteristics are less important than their social characteristics in influencing behavior, and individuals with varying personal characteristics will tend to behave similarly when placed in common situations. D. Situation Theory The political struggle for power follows the same rules in all parts of the world. Human desire to get power can be assumed to be ubiquitous, but it depends on changeable environmental conditions that individuals and groups are capable of getting power and using political institutions for their advantage. Several researchers have contributed possibilities to produce a variety of propositions about the ways executives’ success related to government stability and policy leanings (Ames, 1987). Most 21 empirically-based studies of political development include a thesis that political stability is associated with political development. According to the situational approaches, leadership is highly situational and contextual, and thus a leader is legitimated and gives direction to certain cultural values. It applies to other topics related to political success, i.e., government stability, regime legitimacy, modernization, or political development, cabinet durability or executive durability (Seligman, 1956; Lipset, 1960, 1963 and 1981; Hurwitz, 1973; Schumpeter, 1975; Siedman, 1978; Powell, 1982; Dodd, 1984; Lijphal'ta 1984, 1992; Panebianco, 1988; Mainwaring, 1992). Powell (1982) analyzed political performance as an indicator of political success based on three- dimensions: citizen electoral participation, government stability, and political order. The performance of all political systems is evaluated by durability, civil order, legitimacy and decision efficiency (Eckstein, 1965). The legitimation-crisis paradigm explains that crisis stems from the state’s failure to match its capacity to respond with the level of citizen’s demand and that citizens lose their political confidence in governmental leaders, particularly, top executives. The greater capacity of government in the more modernized societies would enhance executive stability and effectiveness (Ahnond and Powell, 1978). Variations in the exercise of leadership are associated with such contextual factors as domestic socioeconomic conditions, organizational structures, and cultural patterns, or with differences between routine and crisis situations, stable and unstable national or international conditions (Edinger, 1990). Gun (1974) insists that the durability (persistence and adaptability) of political systems depends upon the nature of their structures of political authority such as 22 typological traits, institutionalization, and internal coherence of authority structure. Persistence means how long the system exists and adaptability refers to how well the system responds to the need for changes. As a result, persistence is defined as longevity and this durability as a simple property represents whether a polity is stable. Since failures of the system are the fault of incumbent power holders the situation can be greatly improved by changing the incumbent authorities. The cure for a government and an economy that are performing poorly is a change of leadership - brought about by the democratic process (Lipset and Schneider, 1983, p.390). It seems relevant to consider some important situational factors which determine whether a person is chosen for a leadership position. Considering situational factors, several recruitment studies have discussed career patterns, opportunity structure, and social learning (Seligman, 1964a, 1964b, 1971, 1974; Schlesinger, 1966; Prewitt, 1970; Wriggins, 1969; Stogdill, 1974, 1981). The behavior of political leaders will vary considerably from situation to situation. According to Fiedler (1971), We can now see quite readily why leadership trait will not predict leadership effectiveness. If any one can be an effective leader in some situations and not in others, it is obvious that a single leadership trait or a combination of traits will not enable prediction in all situations. Such a trait or combination of traits may well predict performance in certain situations that can be specified, and this is what the contingencies model [that Fiedler presents] shows (p.15). After examining and comparing the relationship between personality and situational explanations of political behavior, between personality and role explanations of political behavior, and between personality and cultural explanations of political behavior, he concluded that individuals’ social characteristics rather than their personality 23 characteristics determine their political behavior. Even though Huntington (1975, p.251) praised Ayub Khan of Pakistan for coming close "to filling the role of a Solon or Lycurgus or Great Legislator on the Platonic or-Rousseauian Model," Ayub failed to develop legitimate political institutions and to ensure meaningful participation by the people in the political process. The result was a mass upheaval which led to the disruption of the country - political decay. In developing or underdeveloped states, individual leaders tend to be far more legitimate than either existing political institutions or the institutions they may choose to fashion. However, in an ideal sense, legitimacy should reside not only in individual leaders but also in the political institutions of the state. It is much the case in the economically developed states that dominate the development indicators. E. Interaction Theory Recently, leadership has been based on the idea of a capable person being in the right place at the right time. It emphasizes not only individual differences but also different situational aspects. When political leadership is defined as a pattern, it becomes apparent that it is "both a function of social situation and a firnction of personality, as well as a function of these two in interaction (Gibbs, 1947). It shows that the qualities most valued in leaders relate to their ability to reflect the group norms and aspirations, with an added aptitude for improving the group standards and performances. This circularity in the relationships is particularly noticeable within political leadership, and can be accepted as an hypothesis in exploring the nature of leadership. 24 In addition, political leadership is related to personal qualities and circumstance as causative factors of the phenomenon (Dion, 1968, p.4). It can be explained. not only by the conjunction of the nature of the leader (trait theory) but also by the nature of the event, problem, or task, confronting the group (situation theory). It is interesting to examine how the combinations of environmental factors and leader’s backgrounds affect the perceived success of the leader. According to this theory, a leader will emerge as the result of a good fit between the personality of the individual actor and the characteristics of the setting (Kellerman, 1986; Ballard and Suedfeld, 1988). The social structure or situation variables determine political opportunities, personality structure supplies the political motivation, and skills determine the level of political success. As a consequence of the economic, political, and technological changes, political leaders have changed from men with aristocratic, preindustrial backgrounds to businessmen and their advisors and agents, who are typically lawyers. Besides such personal attributes as the individual’s ability and his educational and technical background, what environment factors influence who becomes an effective or successful leader? The interaction theory explains the question of ’becoming political leaders’ based on situation, skill, and psychology (Rajai and Phillips, 1988, p.107). It will answer three interrelated sets of questions: (1) Who are they?; (2) Why and how do they rise to leadership positions?; and (3) In what ways are they similar and how do they differ? Personality factors alone cannot determine who become a leader, especially since some of the factors which determine who becomes a leader are quite outside the individual’s control. Consequently, an explanatory factor that is psychological and a control factor 25 that is sociological can be conceived as two different levels of description. One might regard an attitude as derivative of an objective position or status, or an objective position in society as leading to psychological processes such as attitudes. Edinger (1964) introduced three different models for explaining political success: rational-behavior model, group-behavior model, and actor-centered personality model. Based on the first model, success as a leader is measured by the achievement of certain objectively posited goals and failure by an ability to achieve them. F unctionality- dysfunctionality is perceived by the investigator in terms of the manifest end values which may be achieved by bargaining, persuasion, or coercion. However, the second model explains that functionality-dysfunctionality is evaluated according to means rather than ends. The third model, meanwhile, simply focuses on the individual’s personality need, i.e., ego satisfaction and tension reduction, in evaluating functionality-dysfunctionality. Edinger (1964) claims that leaders’ role performance is evaluated by role congruence. Unless role congruence is restored by changes in the situational determinants and changes in his role performance, it is not easy for the people to agree to his role assignments and to accept him as their leader. A test of successful and effective political leadership would seem to be apparent congruence of the aspiring or actual leaders’ role perception with those of his counter- players in a relevant role-set (Edinger, 1964, p.658). Some scholars have quantified the characteristics of successful presidents and presidential greatness (Wendt and Light, 1976; Sirnonton, 1981, 1984, 1986a, 1986b, and 1987; Nice, 1984). Dean Keith Sirnonton (1984) developed an interaction theory by integrating the great-man and situational theories. According to him, the eponymic 26 significance or sociocultural success of a political leader is determined not only by the impact of the situational context but also by the individual attributes such as intelligence, morality, leadership qualities, productivity, aggressiveness, age, etc. Nevertheless, he concludes that a key predictor of presidential greatness, duration of time in office, may have more situational than individual causes. However, the length of service a particular leader may depend, partly, on personal influence and, partly, on his ability to get himself renominated and reelected. Length of reign is associated not only with the possession of qualities of leadership but also with a nation’s economic, political, military and even cultural well-being. Another example of the combination of situation and personal quality factors is Cell’s (1974) work which has been progressive in the direction of assessing the different levels of charisma displayed by various heads of state. Stogdill (1981) is also interested in the attributes of the leaders and situations. Blondel (1980), more concretely, analyzed political leadership using personalities, careers, socioeconomic backgrounds, and political styles based on the interactional theory. He systematically dealt with every national chief executive who held office from the end of World War II to the 19703, although he did so to provide a purely descriptive explanation. Especially, as the question of succession related to the popularity of the leader in office and of the leader or leaders who might replace the politician in power, regularity of succession related to the strength or pull of these leaders on the population (p.102). He claims that the strength of a leader depends on various characteristics of his own personal characters as well as the political system. Recently, Bienen and Van De Walle’s (1991) approach to leadership longevity 27 describes and explains the patterns of risks for losing power that leaders face. Their purpose of the study is to explore the probability of a leader’s loss of power over different intervals of time without relating leadership longevity to power enhancement. or regime stability. Nonetheless, their models focus on individual leader traits and country traits based on the event-history approach. The maintenance of political leadership position rests on a system of social exchange or transaction (Burns, 1976). The structure and dynamics of the relations between leaders and followers are the main themes in the transaction theory. According to Hollander (1978), when leaders are effective, they give something and get something in return. Power and conflict always exist in the relationship between leaders and followers. He combines the situational approach with a social exchange component that focuses on reciprocal influence between the leader and the followers. Philosophical concern with conflict reaches back to Hobbes and even Heraclitus, and men who spurred revolutions in Western thought, such as Machiavelli, Hegel, Marx, Freud, and Feuerbach. The theories of Pareto, Durkheim, Max Weber and others contain many concepts, assumptions, and hypotheses which greatly influenced later writers who attempted to deal with conflict in general; and George Sirnmel carried theories of conflict into 20th centuries. According to Hegel, Marx, Feuerbach, conflict produces consciousness. In other words, leaders can make followers more conscious of aspects of their identity, such as sexual, communal, ethnic, class, national, and ideological, etc. Leadership style is regarded as the nature of the relationship between leaders and followers. In this sense, agents from the perspective of followers would be moral and political culture within which they operate and social formulations from 28 which they are drawn. Even though political leadership is explained as the interaction between leaders and followers, it is not easy to examine or demonstrate this relationship retroactively in the historical contexts with which we deal (Rajai and Phillips, 1988, p.4). CHAPTER II Theoretical Perspectives of Political Success The political leadership approach suffers from argument and confusion over key terms, a relative dearth of testable hypotheses, a failure to clearly separate normative from empirical theory and, not least, the lack of a firm data base in which the latter could be solidly grounded (Mayser and Wagstaffe, 1987, p.1). The lack of conceptual focus cannot be attributed to either philosophy or method, whether verbal or quantitative, empirical or normative (Lindblom, 1968). The concepts and hypotheses of the leadership perspective on one hand, and its methods and techniques on the other, have been quite heavily criticized. At a given point of time, each government has only one government; at the top of the government is a supreme authority - whether individual or collective - a single leader or a cabinet. Every political system must have its legitimate rulers. For instance, formal-legal authority of individuals in key policymaking positions, that is, presidents and prime ministers, depends on the question of the institutionalization of effective executive authority. Individual leadership at the top is based principally on the legitimate powers of the highest governmental positions. According to Max Weber’s rules, some leaders gain legitimacy from legal-rational norms, some from traditional norms, and others from charismatic norms. Authority and legitimacy imply the recognition of a right to hold office as well as the general consent to the rules of the political system. Legitimacy refers to the overall level of acceptance of the regime or government 29 30 throughout the polity. The legitimacy of authority in a given country has been evaluated by the legitimacy of the rulers dependent on any particular standards of righteousness or. performance. There are neo-utilitarian theories that make regime legitimacy dependent on the effectiveness and efficiency of government in providing A more life satisfaction for the worst part of society and, eventually, good and equal satisfaction for everyone (Handerich, 1976). For a leader’s authority as a top executive, his or her hold upon the follower’s loyalty and willingness to follow, will depend in some measure upon the effectiveness or ineffectiveness of the leadership performance from the follower’s point of view (Tucker, 1991, pp.41-42). The effective control of political leaders requires creating a stable political order and securing the legitimacy of political rule. It is persuasively agreed that the great majority of any population has a strong tendency to see their head of government as their nation, and to give legitimacy not only to the person but to the acts of that person. The failure of political institutions to manage rapid social and economic change is viewed as a major contributor to crisis of legitimacy and national integration. And, if such failure happens, a leader might be vulnerable to reprimand. Over the decades, political leadership has been explained by two different perspectives. One is that leaders are viewed either as heroic and famous figures (charismatic or traditional leaders). Another is that leaders are viewed as the agents from the perspective of followers (legal-rational leaders). While the former is explained by the traits, personality and skills theory, the latter is supported by the situational theory. A precise assessment on the impact of leaders can be made in two crucial respects; the popularity of leaders among the population and the attitudes of citizens to 31 various issues. However, the recent trend seems to be a combination of the two perspectives. The qualities of political leaders, the immediate moral and political culture within which they operate, and the social formulations from which they are drawn are all parts of the equation. It is clear that the advantage of any particular qualities of individual leaders or situational influence varies not only from country to country, but also from time to time in any given country. As long as the exercise of power includes a relationship between those who exercise it and those who are subject to it, longevity has often been linked to stability and performance (Black, 1966; Rustow, 1967; Huntington, 1968; Eckstein, 1971). The stability of the state and the regime and the effectiveness of the public authorities seem to depend on the way in which the institution of the chief executive is organized and fitted with the other institutions of the nation. The longevity of a chief executive is related to the legitimacy of the institution, partly because this will give stability to the institution and partly because the efficiency of the government is also at stake. The efficient institution of the chief executive will become more legitimate as time passes, while one which is inefficient will lose credibility. The ’credibility’ of leaders is an essential aspect of governmental life. However, the support of a leader and his policies does not always include the gaining of legitimacy to the larger systems of the state and the lack of support for a specific leader or a policy does not always imply a lack of overall legitimacy. No society remains unchanged throughout all time. As long as the problem of political order or stability is compounded by the problem of legitimacy, analysis of 32 political success should be focused on leadership performance. Moreover, the comparative approach calls for a common theoretical framework by means of which the relationship between the legitimacy aspect of leadership and the socioeconomic and political structures of several countries may be analyzed. The interaction between the approaches to legitimacy of the leaders and of the structures within which they led can be studied comparatively in order to ascertain whether or not there is a relationship between this interaction and their success or failure in maintaining legitimate authority. The nature and interrelationships of patterns of authority, levels of modernization, methods of citizen mobilization, and levels of industrialization, etc. should be considered as important factors in a political leadership equation. The concept of legitimacy is elusive and it is not easy to operationalize. However, much literature has looked for a number of specific ingredients which could enter into the composition of legitimacy and which could be more easily operationalized (Rogowski, 1974, pp126-27). Legitimacy and political integration are affected by variations in general social and economic conditions. If a society is static and relatively insulated from the influence of other polities, the relative strength of the regime or government will not tend to change. Where integration is high, it will remain high. Where groups and political system are not in harmony, conflict will remain high, as in plural societies. Political instability represents a crisis for a nation and its rulers. According to Morrison and Stevenson (1971, p.348), it induces a situation in which institutionalized authority patterns in a nation break down and political violence replaces compliance with political authorities. Thus, political stability defined as the endurance and 33 persistence of regimes over time is measured by the length of time that particular constitutional arrangements have been in place or that modernizing leadership has been in control. A. The Concept of Political Survival as Political Success In a general sense, success is explained by the idea that individual decisiveness should be added to luck. Whereas luck is the probability of getting what you want without trying, success is how often one gets what one wants if one tries. However, in political leadership, much of what makes for success is out of the individual’s hands. According to Lasswell and Lerner (1965), men seek to maximize ’valued outcomes’ by adopting ’institutional practices’ that also affect the ’resource environment.’ One of the valued outcomes is ’power’ outcome that includes a final decision as winning or losing an election or a war. Sinclair (1993) also claims that a solid initial basis for gauging degree of success or failure is whether or not a president advances his goals. According to one standard, if a president accomplishes what he sets out to achieve, or if he attains his own goals whatever they happen to be, he is a success. What constitutes a ’successful leader,’ is considered a matter of definition in terms of the problem under investigation. He may be a man who gets things done, such as furthering economic development or winning elections or wars; he may be a leader who maintains the ’stability’ of a political system in terms of stress or who introduces major innovations into political processes (Edinger, 1969, p.10). It is clearly in accord once with the fact that successful leaders are career leaders who devote long years of careful grooming to the political roles they eventually come to assume, whereas 34 unsuccessful leaders are crisis leaders who are susceptible to the forefront without much preparation and typically in response to situations of national emergency. According to Fred Riggs’ (1981) argument, the political leaders who fall into the successful category found their legitimacy on a mixture of norms congruent with the structures within which they led.’ As a result, their success is determined by the interaction of their leadership strategies, the cultural symbols that they are able to manipulate, and the institutional and social contexts within which they operate. Support relates to legitimacy, and legitimacy stems from individual support. Where positive and passive support exceeds negative reactions, the regime can be said to be relatively legitimate; the greater the difference in favor of positive support, the higher the amount of legitimacy. This enables the public authorities to continue in office. The. citizens in a constitutional state are free to criticize openly the nature of governmental decisions, to propose alternatives and to take forms of constitutionally recognized action to change laws and policies. Therefore, respect for political office and a disposition to obey must be the primary elements in political authority (Carter, 1979, p. 33). Support is explained by two issues: (1) Who wins and who looses in political competition?; and (2) Why and how do politics persist or change? (Eckstein, 1979) Succession process is one useful way of observing the legitimacy of a system. How is political leadership transferred from one man to another and from one party to 5 His model is called as prismatic model that combined three norms from Max Weber such as charismatic norms, traditional norms, and legal-rational norms. If a president is a head of the party as well as a head of government, it is not a prismatic model. The criteria to evaluate the leaders successful or not are based on the combination of three norms. 35 another? The succession process is a useful checkpoint for looking at the question of legitimacy because when power is transferred, individuals within the system are forced to decide whether their loyalties are confined to those who have exercised authority or to the system of government itself. For example, the executives’ inability to maintain consistent support has directly caused regime instability and encouraged military coups. In the case of persistent incongruence, the voters will not support the central actor, a revolution will overthrow him, his formal subordinates will fail to execute his orders (Edinger, 1964, p.659). ‘ The hurt of withdrawal affects every leader, no matter what its cause and no matter how power passes. It does not matter if a powerholder is thrown out of office, comes to the end of a legally limited term, or leaves of his own accord; there is a feeling of emptiness and a sense of having done something wrong. Even those who seek power to accomplish a goal - and accomplish it - even they leave office with regret, a fear of boredom, and a vague sense of shame. The loss of power is the realization of how badly they had exercised it. So from a psychological aspect, the method of losing power would make a difference. A successfirl leader holds a position as a chief executive until natural death or the end of a constitutional term, followed by voluntary retirement. If the nature of leadership is considered as a structured pattern of authority and subordination, the leadership is not simply a function of the leader acting by himself, but the result of an interaction with the people. A successful leader may be an individual whose role interpretations are accepted by the salient counter-players because he satisfies their expectations, or he may be a person who so clearly comprehends the political context 36 that he can adjust his behavior to meet the expectations of these relevant others (Edinger, 1964, p.665). Political legitimacy is a key to creating a viable polity capable of sustaining national development and without it, development efforts are likely to be futile and their achievements in administration or any other field are apt to be short-lived. The credibility of leaders and of institutions is an essential aspect of governmental life. If people withdraw their consent from any leader, that leader could find it difficult, almost impossible, to continue in a leadership role. In the end, people remove and replace any leaders from whom they have withdrawn consent. The lack of legitimacy leads to the lack of authority on the part of the political leadership and the lack of self-compliance on the part of subject people. Nevertheless, in reality, the polity is managed for survival of the leadership rather than for equitable development of the polity. In many societies, it seems that leadership and the use of power are inextricably woven together. Many leaders can mobilize the high legal and administrative bureaucracies of the state in massive displays of power. However, the effective use of power requires social legitinrization. In all sociocultural systems, leaders should mobilize human, material, and symbolic resources of society toward specific social ends. They should have abilities to maintain their regimes. Legitimacy is threatened not so much by one who would break the rules as by one who seems to break trust in the image of the presidents or the prime ministers as dignified, plain and clean in character. A system which failed miserably would lack legitimacy and would, therefore, be a prime candidate for extinction or fundamental system change. If a nation’s political performance, legitimacy, and persistence are all threatened, political 37 instability accrues. Leadership success is increasingly evaluated on the basis of the fulfillment of directives. Gupta (1990) stresses two capacities to gain legitimacy among the people: the democratic form of government and the maintenance of economic prosperity. Even though executive durability is defined as the government stability in democratic regimes in most studies, especially in parliamentary government, it is possible to apply for all different government styles including communist systems. According to Lipset (1959), legitimacy involves the capacity of a political system to engender and maintain the belief that the existing political institutions are the most appropriate or proper ones for the society. Besides the promise of economic prosperity, leaders can hold on to power through an appeal to the national ideology. Focused on the chief executive as a target, a measure for the evaluation of a leader’s performance should be related to government stability or to the durability of a chief executive. The definition of stability demonstrates considerable staying power and a capacity to endure without great or frequent changes in pattern. All countries emphasize on economic growth and political stability, and these are main factors to prolong the leader’s tenure. However, it is not right to say that a definition of stability is merely longevity, even if we would agree on just how long a democracy must endure to be considered stable. For example, the presence of short-lived governments is taken as an evidence of poor performance in all regimes. Also, the tenure of an emergent political leader is frequently short-lived. Political success can be explained by stability of political government that are measured by the tenure of a chief executive. The primary criterion for maintaining leadership position is the satisfaction of the members 38 of the society. The power motive is one of the most relevant explanatories to political behavior. The desire for ego enhancement and for manipulating others have been suggested as important in understanding political orientations. All leaders seek power, and, if they get into power, they want to keep power as long as possible. Power as a head of government is a function of the leader’s will to arouse and tap the needs and wants of followers and his capacity to mobilize resources to meet those needs and wants, thereby contriving to retain followers’ support and to continue in power (Burns, 1978, p.386). The exercise of leadership depends more or less on his performance in the roles that an individual in a high political office may play. According to Sirnonton (1986), one of the indicators of presidential success or greatness is ’years in office’, a variable that is used to predict most of the variance in presidential success. It is actually based on eponym theory such that long-lived rulers may provide history with eponyms, that is, with convenient names for the epochs of history. In a narrow sense, a climb up the political ladder from lower status to national office means political success to political figures. If they become heads of government, there is no place to move up. Therefore, in a broad sense, political success means strong durability in office. Political success, that is, continued tenure in office, depends on the impression that the office-holder is handling his job competently. Power comes with office, and leadership rests on force or on consent. It is important to combine power with authority to be an effective powerholder. Power is often treated as synonymous with ’authority’, and authority is commonly referred to as ’legitimate’ power. To the leaders who finish their career or their life, leadership means 39 the culmination of their career. Of those who come into power, some will leave it honored with the glow of a job well done and a memory of themselves carved into history. Some will leave it with a feeling of frustration and failure that can reach to the deepest levels of despair. Some will fail in the eyes of others but find a way to look upon it in another light. They succeed in not being successfully challenged before the end of their working life. If they do not succeed in staying at the head of their country until retirement, they are less successful or less fulfilled than those previously illustrated. Whether a leader is formally appointed, formally elected for a specified term of office, he has to rely on the acceptance of his acceptance by his followers. B. The Concept of Head of Government While Tucker (1981) argues that leadership approach to the nature of politics is distinct from power approach since leadership is a value-neutral phenomenon, Janda , (1972) asserts that a positional view relates to the concept of ’power’. It is true that leadership is not identical to power. However, it is a certain kind of power, or it is the use of power in some circumstances. The individuals in political institutions and groups who exercise more influence than others on the allocation of values are considered key concepts in explaining political leadership (Huntington, 1971, p.316). According to Jennings (1960), political leadership is concentrated on formal leaders - the holders of official positions of authority, and especially those in national politics. Political leadership, as concept and category of analysis, is constant, while its actual membership or personnel composition is variable. It varies from society to society, depending upon such factors as historical tradition, past political experience, 40 foreign influence, ideological predilection of society, or simple happenstance. There exist differences in forms of society-wide political leaders from a cross-cultural, historical, and evolutionary perspective. The leadership of a society is a criterion of the values by which that society lives. Also, by learning the nature of the leaders, we learn much about the nature of the society. Political leadership is a role that is understood in terms of the social and cultural context within which it is embedded and which shapes the particular forms it takes in any society. Many political scientists also define the concept of political leader in many different ways. A leader is the one who occupies the position or fills the role that allows him or her to wield the greatest power. Dahl’s professional politician, Snyder’s political decision-maker, Lasswell’s policy scientists and Deutsch’s cybernetic leadership are other examples. In addition, more specifically, Ilchman and Uphoff’s (1971) statesman is a political actor as a head of regime. Apparently, identical or similar conceptualizations are often translated into very different operational criteria for empirical research; and seemingly different ones are operationalized in much the same way (Edinger, 1969). The analyses in this study would be largely confined to the heads of government considering both positional and power-related concepts. Success of political leaders will be regarded as one of the outcomes of political leadership, since it depends on how they, as heads of government are evaluated or perceived by the people in their society. Whatever the political system is, i.e., the Western democracies or the communist states, it is true that an individual or the collective occupies the unique position of being at the apex of the pyramid of often absolute power. The main mediator between 41 constitutive system and bureaucracy is the head; the head of the government; the head of state; the head of political party; the head of the armed force. Sometimes these roles are united in one person, but often they are separated so that a polity has several heads at once. In constitutional regimes, the head has a formal title, but under naked rule, the most important head could be a boss who rules from behind the scenes, while those with formal leadership titles are mere ’puppets’. For instance, the gradual displacement of dynastic rule in Europe by constitutional monarchies and republics produced a differentiation between a head of state, symbolizing the society as politically organized, and a head of government. Among all the heads, the role of a head of government (chief executive) is the most important in practicing actual power, since the executive branch is both the prime mover and the principal regulator of governmental performance. In modern constitutional regimes, the chief executive is chosen through the constitutive system. The chief executive can be chosen by the elected assembly in a parliamentary system, by the electorate in a presidential system; or by the chairman of the party, etc. The very nature of elections - the typical process for filling political office in a democratic society - entails the selection of those with good qualifications for office. Electing someone need not imply any belief in his inherent superiority, but it does usually imply belief in competence and so the right, which stems from being qualified, of the specific individual to hold that office (Carter, 1979, p.34). Therefore, this dissertation will include the political leaders who are or were in actual power in each regime, that is, the heads of governments across the nations. Regimes have frequently been classified by their most ’visible features’, which 42 has meant a classification based on either the different forms or the different styles that political leadership has taken. However, traditional classification of regime type or forms of government is more or less meaningless. Even though the division based on the idea of a separation of powers, i.e., executive, legislative and judicial, applies to the presidential system, it does not fit into the parliamentary system. Every country has someone at its head, but there are considerable variations in the extent to who is at the head. Historically, executives formed the central core or kernel of governments, out of which, separate legislative and judicial institutions progressively emerged and broke off. For an example, the term ’executive’ may refer to what in Britain is usually termed ’the government’ and in the USA. ’the administration’. Or it may refer to an even narrower set of ruling institutions and individuals who possess ultimate decision-making power, such as the Politburo and General Secretary in the USSR and other communist states, the ruling juntas in military regimes, and, of course, presidents, prime ministers and their cabinets (Charlton, 1986, p.18). Some countries have a group of people running the countries, such as a presidium, a revolutionary council, or even a council of ministers. A classification of contemporary types of political executives may most logically begin by focusing on heads of governments. According to Blondel (1984), they would be the ’varied and diverse’ nature of executive types among contemporary regimes. They would be included in three dominant categories - monarchs, presidents, and prime ministers. The special categories of members of ruling councils and Communist party secretaries in communist states have to be added to those. It focuses on the leaders who are really in charge of the overall aspects of policy making or the overall view of 43 the affairs of the government. From this point of view, all formal ’heads of state’ who merely symbolize the nation with pure monarchy system should be eliminated. Those nations are Afghanistan before 1973, Bhutan, Brunei, Bahrain, Kuwait, Morocco, Saudi Arabia, Swaziland, Oman, Jordan, Qatar, and the United Arab Emirate. Also, the presidents of the collective council (Uruguay during 1955 - 1965) or rotating presidents (Switzland and Yugoslavia since 1980) are eliminating from the sample. Since most contemporary state are republics, it is not surprising to find that the largest groups of contemporary heads of government are presidents. The limited presidency is the most common form of political executive in the world today, about 52 countries having adopted it, embracing 25% of the global population. Presidential systems based on liberal-democratic ideology, imply rigid forms of succession. Those systems lead to fixed terms of office and organize a separation of powers. It does not allow a president to stay in office, even if he is popular, after a stated period because he is not normally allowed to succeed himself or to stay in office more than a limited time. Some presidents are elected for a limited period only and may not be reelected immediately or, at most, may be reelected only once.6 Bans or restrictions on reelection are for a check on presidential power as well as a safeguard against an executive’s self-perpetuation in office (Shugart and Carey, 1992, p.88). As the forms 6 In some countries such as Brazil (since 1988), Ecuador (since 1979), Guatemala (since 1986), Honduras (since 1985), South Korea (since 1988), Mauritania (since 1980), Mexico, and Uruguay, through the denial of immediate reelection, a time limit is put into presidential term. Where reelection is permitted, it is allowed only after one or two intervening terms in Bolivia, Colombia, Costa Rica, El Salvador, and Venezuela. Also, some countries, such as Austria, Liberia, Nicaragua, Paraguay, Peru, Sierra Leone, Taiwan, Tanzania, and U.S.A., allow just second consecutive terms. However, these constitutional restriction will be ignored for the test. 44 of authoritarian presidency, military rulers often introduce some forms of civilian structure in order to prolong their tenure. The form of ruling collectivities or councils is common in military regimes where the designation of one officer as chief executive frequently obscures the genuinely shared character of the executive leadership group which takes power following a coup d’etat. Secondly, historically, the prime ministers who emerged from beneath the wings of monarchs, have entrusted originally with the subordinate tasks of leading the state bureaucracy and coordinating the institutions of governmental decision-making. In a multiparty parliamentary system, it can consist of a coalition of leaders of several parties. Prime ministers emerged as the heads of the bureaucracy of the State, even though it may not always be true to say that they are always ’first among equals’. They control their party and the parliamentary majority and, if electoral support is maintained, exercise control for long periods. The final type of contemporary political leaders are first or general secretaries of ruling Communist parties. Since communist states are led by a Communist party which is viewed as the vanguard of the nation, the leader of the Communist Party - nominally the first or general secretary - is in effect the country’s leader. The Party Secretariat has, as one of its many executive functions, the duty to oversee and supervise the ’state’ bureaucracy which is formally headed by a prime minister or a president in the communist countries. He embodies the permanent legitimacy of the nation. The communist leader is chosen from among existing leaders, normally concentrated in the politburo and the Secretariat such as the hierarchical structures in which the decisions of higher bodies places major decision-making powers in the 45 topmost organs of the Party. As far as authority or legitimacy implies recognition of a right to hold office and implies general consent to the rules of the political system, in a situation, in which a leader is the main beneficiary of popular authority in the nation, this leader is at liberty to organize his government as he chooses (Blondel, 1982, p.27) C. Theoretical Model We generally, speak of a government as an institutionalized pattern of rule. The rules or governs may constitute a vast and complicated design, as in modern constitutional regimes, or they may be monocratically arraigned in one simple hierarchy, as in aristocratic regimes, including totalitarian dictatorship. Every political system may contain some institutionalized means of recruiting leaders. Also, every political system may have overall ethical evaluation of the quality of their rule. The normative question ’who should rule?’ indicates ’on the basis of what principle of selectivity should political leaders be chosen?’ However, for the empirical aspect, it is important to examine the leaders who in fact did rule. As far as the concept of political leadership is narrowed to ’heads of government’ or ’chief executives’, the political leadership can be explained in a certain view. When we evaluate some leaders successful or unsuccessful, we can focus on how long a leader has been in his/her office. In general, longer the leader stays, the more successful his/her rule is. As discussed in the literature review, the interaction theory has dealt with the combination of traits and situation, social backgrounds and situation, or traits and social 46 backgrounds. However, theoretical development for the analysis, here, employs a combination of the social background theory and the situation theory except the personality and skills theory. We can cast the search in the light of the interaction theory of political leadership stressing the interplay of two approaches described above. The scientific development of political leadership studies - ranging from initial conceptualization through creation, Operationalization, and testing of hypotheses to rigorous theoretical integration at the highest reaches of mathematical imagination - will be promoted by pursuit of a multimodal research strategy. Nonetheless, in the descriptive analyses, personality and skills variables are used for comparison. The problem of keeping a leadership position is complicated because the leader’s authority does not derive solely from the political organization. Authority does not just flow from the top down. Rather, a primary criterion for maintaining the leadership position is how much people are satisfied with their leader. Whether a leader is formally appointed, or formally elected for a specified term of office, he has to rely on the acceptance of his authority by people. As a result, leaders’ success in their offices result from the attitude of the people toward them. The leaders’ social backgrounds, career backgrounds, and situational factors are considered as main criteria by which people evaluate their leaders. This study will focus on predictive and causal analyses. Basically, the analyses are not only the specification of leadership outcomes that are the object of prediction but also the specification of different backgrounds that are hypothesized to predict leadership outcome, that is, duration in office, and the specification of the theoretical linkages among independent variables and dependent leadership outcome. The social, 47 economic, and cultural characteristics of the society in which the organization is embedded are also critical influences on the nature of leadership. As a result, the main research is concerned with the relationship between political leaders’ success and their social backgrounds, career backgrounds, and situational factors. Whether or not a leader becomes successful depends on the possession or acquisition of certain key attributes and experiences. Here, this study tries to get some answers for the possibilities of the research on political leadership. The variable items are adapted from several general pieces of literature of leadership analysis. The variables to be considered are based on scholarly consensus. The variables for which data are collected interrelate to a large extent since demographic, ideological, attitudinal, psychological, and situational variables not only cohere as distinct groups, but also intersect at many points. Hypotheses about political behavior that were ’tested and proven’ valid at one moment in history need to be rechecked constantly against the changes of time and circumstances. The models include several different possible explanations: (1) the leader’s social and career backgrounds; (2) the causes of stability and instability of types of government in the contemporary world; (3) the governmental policies; and (4) the country characteristics, etc. These anticipatory variables simply alert attention to things that may help to describe, explain, predict, evaluate, and intervene. A theoretical model is constructed as follows: Political Success = f (Individual Social Backgrounds, Career Backgrounds, Institutional Attributes). 48 However, as an indicator of political success, duration of office, has somewhat different roles to evaluate political leadership. ’Duration of office’ decides whether a leader stayed for a ’SHORT’ or a ’NOT-SHORT’ period, that is, political survival. After that, it can examine whether he is more successful than others, that is, strength of political survival. Inclusion of the leaders who are still in power into the analysis will need some manipulation in order to reduce misspecification errors. The specification of the model is : Pr( Duration of Office ) = f (Individual Social Backgrounds, Career Backgrounds, Institutional Attributes). Truly, one of the most difficult tasks in measuring and evaluating performance of political leaders is the task of trying to look at the elements that make up political success. The dependent variable in the theoretical model denotes the leadership outcome, whereas a variety of causative factors that extend from very general explanations to highly specific reasons are regarded as the independent variables. Various measures of selected independent variables contribute importantly to the explanation of variance in measures of duration of office. Independent variables are divided into three different subsets: demographic attributes, career attributes, and institutional attributes. Individuals’ personal backgrounds are divided into two groups, demographic or social attributes and career attributes, with the former being caused by nature and the latter beeing caused by experiences. Political scientists on political leadership assume that research on this subject should focus on the behavior or attitudes of political 49 leaders. Therefore, interviews or surveys with them would be the best way to get the data for the research. However, political leaders, as heads of government, especially at the international level, are quite often inaccessible, and attitudinal information is therefore difficult to obtain. There are relatively few variables which are susceptible to quantification that are of greater concern to the political scientists than those describing the backgrounds of political leaders. Even though it is possible to appreciate on a cumulative basic changes that are occurring in the characteristics that define political leaders worldwide, if possible, information on political leaders should be kept and analyzed as qualitative data. The demographic (social background) backgrounds consist of age, place of birth, education, major, father’s occupation, and father’s SES, which are considered as family legacy and political socialization. The career backgrounds are represented by political ideology, party membership, experience in congress, experience as a Minister, previous occupation, military experience, experience in prison or exile, political activity, long- term foreign experience, enter mode, and numbers of entry as a head of government. These variables could be the criteria for evaluating whether a leader has enough qualification for handling the office as a head of government. Personal disposition variables imply the aggregate characteristics such as personality and skills that define a unique human individual (physiological factors; psychological factors, etc.). Even though the role of personality appears to be large, there still exist difficulties in measuring and assessing. A lot of studies of personality have dealt with a number of elements such as energy, courage, intelligence, etc. 50 However, this study, relating to the concept of ’power’, just focuses on ’psychological traits’ and ’task-oriented’ traits. Oral skills, organization skills, and language skills, physiological status, loss of parents or separation from parents in early age, and power connection are included in this subset. Based on a theory of democratic development, institutional, socioeconomic and cultural aspects are very important. As institutional variables, several country characteristics and political systematic variables such as population density, homogeneity index, freedom status, party system, economic freedom, literacy rate, type of head of government, and region as cultural difference, and etc. are used for the models. In an institutional aspect, the degree of individual freedom and participatory rights, competitiveness in party system capable of aggregating diverse interests should be considered as main indicators for evaluating leader’s performance. Developments in education (literacy rate) and economic freedom as criteria for industrialization are also indicators for a nation’s social and economic achievements. Homogeneity index and population density are more related to govemability that a leader can handle problems of his own country. While all variables in personal background attributes may possibly be used in descriptive analyses in order to compare the leaders across the different aspects, some selected variables are included in a statistical model based on certain theoretical perspectives and some variables are deliberately combined for certain roles. The following diagram (Figure 1) shows the model in a very clear manner. 51 Figure 1 Political Success Duration of Office I l l l Demographic Attributes Career Attributes Institutional Attributes Age ' Political Experience Age of Country Place of Birth Long Term Foreign Population Density Experience . Education (Degree) Homogeneity Index P Identification arty Literacy Rate En Mode try Party System Previous Occupation . Economic Freedom Freedom Status Type of Head of Government Region CHAPTER III Theoretical Propositions Legitimacy is an idea of central importance in political thought and science although the concept has proven difficult to use in comparative politics. If a polity lasts for a long time without disruptive changes, it is considered durable. Furthermore, a polity’s legitimacy is likely to be enhanced by its longevity. Among the changes, a change in the formal power of a top executive, or the government as a whole is considered major. Legitimacy is gained or lost through the performance of incumbent political leaders. Unless a top executive who fails conspicuously in action as a leader manages to conceal the failing the political community - as some tyrannical leaders have done, at least until their death or overthrow - that leader’s authority is likely to suffer as a consequence of the perceived failure (Tucker, 1981, p.42). To achieve any lasting improvement in the polity, whether it be economic development, a sense of nationhood, or an equitable society, a leader must obtain popular support for his goals, and to do this requires strong leadership. Regime legitimacy, in effect, goes beyond the performance of a particular incumbent leader and his or her popularity. The legitimate authority of the government and the support for the incumbent government is narrowly circumscribed as to its functions and largely stripped of the personal features of ascriptive authority. The sources of legitimacy serving as the basis for authority can derive from the forces of tradition, from charismatic, or from an institutional rational-legal system of government. People tend to understand regime legitimacy questions largely as confidence in 52 53 particular office-holders and what they do (Lane, 1979, pp.63-64). The importance of legitimacy is considered a precondition for political stability. To a large extent, legitimacy depends on a social and economic system. In general, personal popularity of a president or a prime minister over a relatively short period (e.g. 2 yrs) will contribute fewer positive flows to the stock of regime legitimacy than an economic crisis over along period (8 - 10 yrs) under different governments will generate negative flows. The object is to explain why some political leaders stay in office for a short period and others do not, or why some individuals demonstrate more successful leadership than others. In every society there are definable paths to political success. The requirements for personal success as political performance in office might vary in a corresponding fashion. ’Years in office’ result from popularity and performance which are multicausal. The reasons can be explained by several components. In the aspect of social and economic environment of the society, conditions of wealth, equality, and shared cultural values, etc. influence the sources of variation in political performance, that is, duration of office. Moreover, the personal qualities that the leaders are expected to have are pretty different to the people in each country. The motivation of being or keeping power longer is one of the reasons as well. In looking at what causes leaders to succeed or fail, one crucial point is how they use the power that accrues to them in the role of leader. Some use of power is clearly necessary for a leader’s own survival, as well as to produce changes, as we witness the fate of leaders who failed to use power at critical times. There also is personal power that is not necessarily linked to office in intelligence, knowledge, and 54 experiences in a specific area. Some possess a deliberate manner of expression as well as a way of holding one’s self in public. Rarely be that as it may be, some have physical attributes such as tall, big, and handsome. While physical factors of stature are easy to trivialize, they are after real and significant determinants of success because there are fairly clear cultural expectations of physical ideals and what we want our leaders to represent in relation to them. The main research is concerned with the relationship between the variances in successful and unsuccessful leadership characteristics and the variances in what it takes to be a long-term political leader. All leaders who keep power do not share the same experience partly because there are all different degrees of power and success, partly because of the differences between individuals in character and backgrounds, and partly because of the differences of situation. In an effort to find common denominators or common determinants of the dependent variable, considerable attention should be devoted to the family backgrounds and early histories, career backgrounds, and situations. The major reason for focusing on the elements above is the implicit assumption that if we know who they are, and were, and how they became political leaders, then we evaluate what they do. A sequence of innate and inchoate forces within the human organism epignetically emerge during the development of individuals in their proximal contacts in families and other naturant groups and in their distal contacts with economic, social, and political habits, customs, institutions, and values as these develop pari passu with and within individuals. The social characteristics of the leaders vary from one political system to 55 another. There are many examples to show how the conditions and requisites for entry into political leadership vary from country to country and in different periods. It is because each society has its own social values that political leaders should have and its principle of legitimacy, which guides the actions of the political leaders and expresses a body of values and ideas accepted by the people. There are relationships between personal backgrounds of political leaders and performance of political leaders. Social origins are important, justifying their focus by arguing that social background is a useful indicator of political success. Leaders need to possess a large array of personal attributes if they are to be successful. The career backgrounds of the leaders play a major role in the determination of policy goals and general orientation of political, life in a country. Background data on the social and career characteristics of the leaders provide no infallible guide to either attitudinal patterns or policy preferences. Leaving aside for the moment such personal attributes as the individual’s ability, his educational and technical background, what environmental factors influence leader’s survival? It seems relevant to consider some important situational factors which determine whether a person is chosen to be a head of government. While the behavior of men or of social systems may be described, and perhaps even predicted, without resource to personality and skills variables, no satisfactory explanation is possible until we understand the psychological link which joins man to his sociopolitical environment, and through which each impinges on the other. As a result, for the lack of consistent or trustful information on personality and skills, the propositions on those elements are excluded from a theoretical model. Specific propositions on the basis of social and career backgrounds as well as situational attributes will be discussed in this chapter. 56 A. Do Social Backgrounds of the Leaders Really Matter for Their Political Survival? The study of social backgrounds can furnish clues for a study of political performance, but the first cannot substitute for the second (Lasswell and Lerner, 1965). The analysis of social background data still performs important functions for socialization and recruitment. A person of a certain age, educational attainment and social status is more likely to be successful in his office. He may be liked, trusted, and respected within the society in which he exists. He should have abilities to attract dedicated followers as well as abilities to command loyalty and dedicated service from a comparatively small group of intimates. The demographic variables are based on the concept of naturalness. When people are born, they get certain social status, gender, age, etc., from their parents. Parents and schools have emphasized the importance of achieving social prominence or social dominance. They contribute socialization process to the young children to learn what an individual is prepared, with varying degrees of success, to meet requirements laid down by other members of society for his behavior in a variety of situations. Proposition 1: Long-lasting leaders are younger on reaching office. Generally, age forms the basic criteria which determine eligibility for specific roles. Without laws to make precise the obligations of office and fix the tenure of heads of government, it is universally acknowledged that leaders will hold power as long as their prestige lasts and with little regard to senility. According to gerontocracy thesis, respect for the aged has been at work in most societies although it has been more 57 common in East rather than in West. In some societies, leadership capacity often makes its appearance relatively late in life, in the form of a strong personality or a strong ego. The leader is either an elder or is assimilated to elders even if he is young. However, the seniority system has its drawback especially in the political arena. As a result, as far both life expectancy and seniority system are working together, if the leaders become top executives at middle age, they stay longer than those at young age. Political leadership correlates positively with middle age (Blondel, 1980). It would seem to be ’natural’ for leaders to be relatively old With a certain tendency for the age distribution of the population. However, considering human’s life expectancy, long leaders are younger on reaching office. In this study with continuous age variable, the proposition should be that the leaders who reached their offices at younger age everywhere are more successful. Proposition 2: . Leaders who were born and raised in urban areas are more likely to stay in office longer. Political success correlates with the exposure to urban life. This variable indicates the social environment that the political leader has been raised in. Urban-bom and raised in urban area influence the leader get more exposed to politics and media. The first role perceived by children tends to be a top political executive - the president, prime minister, or general secretary, etc. In early childhood, they have tendency to identify a top political executive as a parent figure. So they become more successful than those from rural or rural-lived. Proposition 3: Highly educated leader tends to have a longer tenure in office. 58 Educated persons are more aware of the impact of government on their lives and pay more attention to politics. It is because people who have a strong sense of personal effectiveness also tend to feel politically effective. Personal and political efficacy are strongly related to education (Campbell, et al., 1960). Intellectuals play a vital role in formulating, disseminating, or sustaining idea that influences both the theory and practice of politics in most societies. Tucker (1977, p.384) argues that trained and sophisticated insight, the capacity to judge situations _ accurately that comes from experience and intellect, are characteristics of an effective leader and are particularly vital requisites for political leadership in the extremely complex world of today. Formal education is the single most important entrance requirement into the higher circles. Political leaders are among the most educated of all occupational groups. The more highly educated people tend to develop the characteristics of trust, satisfaction, and competence that go with democracy. It is a common place to note that educational levels are the highest in socially favored categories. B. Do Career Backgrounds of the Leaders Have Influence on Their Political Survival? Most leaders of the contemporary world have had a ’nonnal’ career. The majority have been ministers or congressmen before becoming the head of government. Also, most leaders have been involved in party activities. Competence of the leaders _ includes references of each person’s past political experience, ability as a head of government, and his intelligence. Considering the fact that the leaders must be 59 absolutely dedicated to the cause and able to demonstrate that commitment by giving time and effort to it, risking their lives, undergoing imprisonment, exile, persecution, and continual hardship, etc. are very influential to leader’s political survival. Proposition 4: The greater the involvement in a political collectivity, such as parliaments or congresses, ministries, and political parties, the greater the support for the leadership, that is, the political rule of the game. > Ambition theory (Schlesinger, 1966) presupposes a rational assessment by the ’ prospective leaders of their opportunities for success. For the most part, political leaders are far from common men in either their origins or their achievement. Political experience is the best teacher of the art of politics, and the accumulated experiences of generations, concentrated into streams of traditions which flow into and through institutions, such as lineages, professions and schools, colleges and universities, are the sources of the knowledge which enables political classes to be successful (Shils, 1982, p.17). If they have experiences in politically related areas such as parties, congresses, or cabinets, it is easier to ascend to a head of government. To pursue a political career an aspirant must conform to a recruitment process which rather rigidly prescribes his role as a candidate for parliament and a member of the ministry (Edinger, 1964, p.663). Highly experienced public officials are more likely to be selected as potential chief executives. Proposition 5: The successful leaders are likely to be found in law, politics, civil service or military, that is, political sectors that would be regarded as upper-status occupations. 60 The correlation between social status and political power, though consistently positive, is not a ground for assuming that the former is a sufficient or necessary condition for the latter (Prewitt, 1970). Also, there is a tradition of respect for the individual, regardless of his rank and wealth in Western political thought. Nevertheless, higher social status is necessary in order to have higher political opportunities. Political job-chances of those with high social status are considerably better than those with average or low prestige. The primary occupations of the leaders prior to seizing power or assuming highest office are rather diverse. Also, children can be influenced by their father’s occupation in developing their political views. The successful leaders tend to have higher status fathers from the upper and middle class holding such positions as landed gentry, big businessmen, government officials, lawyers, military officers, and politicians. However, the leaders had more politically related professions than their fathers did. While fathers’ occupations provided better chances (high social status or wealth) to enter the realm of politics, the leaders themselves established their careers and used them as stepping-stones to the highest political jobs. Proposition 6: Leaders with foreign experiences, i.e., foreign education and work in foreign countries, are more likely to stay in office for a long period. Foreign experience contributes the leaders ability to develop cosmopolitanism. Abroad, they see different level of development and understand of foreign affairs. Most leaders will tend to heighten their cosmopolitanism by greater foreign travel, foreign study, exposure to various societies and cultures, and maintenance of foreign contacts. 61 They are guided by the idea of adopting and adapting modernized technology through foreign education or foreign experiences. They contribute to making society stable, and, of course, successfully accomplish more. General knowledge is associated with foreign language ability and with understanding of foreign affairs. However, this tendency depends on the level of development of country or reign of country. Proposition 7: If a leader comes to his office in a peaceful way, he is more likely to stay in office longer. In general, some political leaders come to office as a head of government through peaceful processes, whether appointive or elective, while others in violent ways. Some scholars (Rajai and Phillips, 1988) identify these two groups of individuals as follows: The former are ’loyalists’ and the latter are ’revolutionaries’. Since, in this study, just the leaders in single leadership would be discussed, entry mode as an appointment mechanism can be a variable to influence political leadership in republics, presidential or military presidential, and prime ministerial systems. Even though party secretary or general secretary in Communist system is not real single leadership, they are normally stronger than the prime minister. Political leaders, having been chosen and exercising their fimctions in accordance with these rational-legal procedures, can enjoy a high degree of legitimacy. In addition, they need not worry about being humiliated, executed, put in jail, or forced into exile after an overnight coup. Removal from office through constitutional due process or assassination are the major and constant risks to their political survival. If legitimacy is defined in terms of established rules, a government which has come to 62 power by civil war, revolution or coup d’etat can not immediately claim legitimacy, although it may claim authority by virtue of its ideology, goals and popular support, by providing its effectiveness in meeting the country’s needs and by demonstrating the qualities of the new leaders (Carter, 1979, p.51). Proposition 8: Leaders of the right, such as the conservatives, tend to stay longer than those of the left, such as the liberals. While the political left has higher levels of tolerance for democratic liberties than those on the right, the political right is less supportive of democratic norms. It is important to pay attention to the beliefs and values of political leaders, particularly as they relate to sweeping ideological and intellectual movements. Political leaders always possess some sets of philosophical and political convictions that are his own. In order to legitimize any type of regime, the leaders of the regime must devise a political formula and political ideology that gains acceptance among the people at large. Ideology plays a significant part in the life of most parties, both symbolic and practical. They try to shape political institutions in ways consonant with his own political philosophy, even though the goals of the leaders are not necessarily identical to those of the followers and intermediate leaders. They generally identify themselves with the ideologies7 of the right (conservative), the center, or the left (liberal) in terms of their stances toward the size of government, the equalization of social conditions, and the social and economic issues in a country. Ideologies of the left have tended to favor a larger role for government, greater 7 Right means traditional conservative and populist (even if it is a kind of left). 63 equalization of income, govemment-supported welfare programs, and a minimization of unemployment. Meanwhile, the right has tended to favor a more restrained role for government, maintenance of existing income distribution, private welfare, and a minimization of inflation, even at a cost to employment. Usually, the more conservative the ideology of a political leader, the longer he stays in office. It is because social and economic resources based on conservative ideology induce politically stable situations. The promise of radical change in the social, economic, and political fabric, is threatening to political stability. C. How Do the Institutional Attributes Influence Political Survival? Geographical environments, economic systems, social structures and cultural differences provide some assistance to explain political success on a macro level. Geography and demography would be considered as physical attributes of countries. Thus, size of country“, population size, and age of nations might be the main indicators for both attributes and these variables imply govemability or viability, legitimacy of the countries, or vulnerability of the nations. The duration of the country, the unity and the characteristics of the political culture are the indicators for national identity. It is difficult to handle and almost impossible to quantify. Proposition 9: Leaders in densely populated countries are more likely to stay in office for a short period. 8 According to de Blij (1967, p.41), states exceeding one million square miles are generally described as very large, while those under 10,000 square miles are referred to as very small. The category of the size of nation is as follows: Very small ( - 10,000), small (10,000 - 60,000), medium (60,000 - 140,000), and large (140,000 - ). 64 There may be considerable variation in the potential contribution of geographical elements in achieving the basic objectives that usually underlie state interventions: (1) the provision of security and order, related to the defense of a territory; (2) the stimulation of economic growth and well-being; and, (3) the guarantee of social justice, etc. Geographical space can fulfill the realm of government actions, demonstrating the rationale of functions on the grounds of either efficiency or equity criteria. In addition, the application of policies requires some spatial considerations for the same purpose to get efficiency or equity. The problems of size as related to effective national control and politico- territorial organization are nothing new in the history of state evolution. As seen in the literature review, Montesquieu already mentioned the regime types based on the size of country. According to the previous cross-national studies, population size has an influence on government performance or government stability since it affects overall rates of political change. As a result, the more densely populated countries are more unstable because high level of population density becomes a main source of change and social dislocation. Consider the redistributional element of public programs, where the spatial distribution of benefits to individuals and household ought to be in accOrd with population - which is in fact the case for education, health, housing, and income- maintenance benefits. Governments of small countries have to deal with qualitatively less heterogeneous societies - similar attitudes, values, and beliefs. In a general sense, a chief executive in a country with small population is more likely to be successfirl in office. 65 Actually, country sizes run the gamut from the minute Vatican - less than one- sixth of a square mile - to that of the giant former Soviet Union, over 8.5 million square miles prior to the collapse of the Eastern Block. With respect to country size, it is easier to keep order in smaller nations (Lijphart, 1977; de Blij, 1967). In a small nation it is easier for authorities to perceive when discontent is smoldering and to act to prevent its outbreak, either through suppression or by alleviating its causes. Meanwhile, in large nations, the information processes work less well, and control is more difficult; hence, outbursts are more likely. Small countries offer better requisites for the creation of the spirit of cooperativeness and an accommodation, which is crucial for the maintenance of democracy (Lijphart, 1977, p.65). In such countries, it is probable that the political leaders will be more united through personal acquaintance and interaction. Proposition 10: In older countries, leaders tend to have longer duration in office. As one of the indicators for legitimacy, age of nationhood is very important. An older country is more likely to have achieved a high level of national identity than a newer country. An older country is stronger, having usually lived through a number of crises. The political leaders in the older countries are likely to be more successful since those countries tend to have institutional stability and political tranquillity. It'is because opportunities for succession are more numerous in older countries. Irregularities of succession are rare among very new countries. This proposition is pretty much related to colonial experience of the country. Colonial experience in each country’s history reflects the establishment of her own background. Even though one country is located in a certain region and has been 66 sharing same cultural influence in that region, if she has been affected by foreign power, her own culture should have been changed in some degree. The new states were handed down the political and administrative structure of the imperial nations. For example, the British built up a fairly well-functioning administrative system in the colonies, imposing a kind of indirect rule. France, meanwhile, applied a markedly centralized administrative system, which was sustained in all essentials by officials from the home country. Thus, the population of the French colonies became less involved in the exercise of authority. As a result, the states which the British left behind would, for these reasons, be better equipped for democratic government than those which had belonged to France. The impact of colonialism on the traditional societies of Asia and Africa is significant. Low modernization is associated with low participation, low competitiveness, and fewer political parties. Lower levels of modernization are related to a party system which is relatively less complex and characterized by low competitiveness where a single party has been established as the dominant one (Huntington, 1968). As indicators of structural attributes, we may use party system, economic. system, and cabinet size may be formally used. The issue of political success is related to whether the political leaders have legitimacy and efficiency. An efficient institution of a chief executive will become more legitimate as time passes, while one which is inefficient will lose credibility. To keep a position as a prime minister or a president, an individual must have a strong desire for office and a willingness to do whatever the system requires to reach the top. If legitimacy entails the involvement of many groups in the selection of the chief 67 executive as well as in the decision-making process, the result may be a reduction in efficiency through instability or indecisiveness. Proposition 11: The more fragmented the party system, the more unstable we expect the government to be; and the shorter the leader stays in office. As a result, government stability is negatively correlated with the number of parties in the government. Another line of inquiry focused on the impact of the party system in maintaining political stability (Pridham, 1990). The stability of political leadership depends on party activities in the electoral and legislative arenas. Political parties play a leading role everywhere in legitimizing and institutionalizing the paths of political careers, not only as an instrument for winning and administrating power but also as an instrument best adapted to political struggle. We know that some parties adapt very easily to open competition and the peaceful transfer of political power while others are exclusive and seem unable to react to power alternatives, with the exception of violence. The more diffuse are the party roles, and the more variegated the career paths, the more diverse the people selected thereby. Parties are two-way means of communication of influence between rulers and population. Party system is related to the degree of national integration and dimension of the process of national development and modernization. Economic development is more likely to be realized, given one dominant political party, or a pair of parties, each strongly committed to economic development, as opposed to a multiplicity of parties (Lerner, 1957). The number of parties affects democratic stability (Lipset, 1960; Blondel, 1968; Tylor and Herman, 1971; Sanders and Herman, 1977; Dodd, 1976; 68 F isichella, 1984). If party systems are highly fractionalized, government tends to form in unstable and conflictory political systems. Competitive party systems ensure relatively high levels of turnover in government (Mishler and Hildreth, 1984). A multiparty system tends to depress people’s support for a leader. Meanwhile, a single party system sees itself as synonymous with the entire people and offers less political opportunity and higher political risk than parties in a competitive system. Consequently, leaders in a single party system or a single-party dominated system are more likely to stay longer in office than their counterparts in competitive party systems. A single party system usually leads to a totalitarian system in which the government nevertheless strives to achieve mass political support on the basis of a powerful, visionary ideology. However, a stable multi-party presidential democracy is more difficult to achieve than a two-party presidential democracy or a multi-party parliamentary system (Lijphart, 1992, p.116). Countries with at least one effective governing party are more likely to deal successfully with the problem of succession than are countries where parties are not present. While governing juntas of bureaucrats and military men are rarely prepared for the politics of peacefully electing their own leader or of having leadership peacefully pass from one person to another, at least parties are experiences in the art of internal elections. The strength of environment promotes leader’s success. For example, prosperous economic periods give heads of government more chances to obtain their success. Economic development fosters democratic political stability; the state’s capacity to promote economic effectiveness is itself a key ingredient in Lipset’s 69 formulation of stability. The economy’s infrastructure such as wealth, industrialization, education (literacy), and urbanization, leads to the emergence of viable political performance (Lipset, 1981, pp.27-86). Long leadership tends to exist in countries where the extent of social and econorrric change is low. If the freedom of social, political, and economic areas is guaranteed, the changes will be less. Thus, the society tends to very stable and the political leader will stay in office longer. Economic freedom, freedom index as a combination of political right index and civil right index, homogeneity index, urbanization, and literacy are used as indicators of economic and sociopolitical development for the hypotheses testing. Proposition 12: The lower the extent of social and economic change, the longer the leadership will tend to prevail. The level of economic freedom depends on what economic system the society is in. While economic systems vary considerably among cultures, they can generally be analyzed by looking at who manages the system and how, and upon what basis the goals are distributed. Democracy is associated with a certain form of economic organization, namely capitalism. Capitalism promoted a dispersion of power in society which creates a favorable basis for political democracy. Meanwhile, under socialism, a strongly concentrated, organizationally coherent economic and political power breeds passivity and fear among both the citizens and potential opposition parties. No one dares to seriously resist the political leaders who control his livelihood (Schumpeter,l975). Especially, in the turbulent politics of 70 developing nations, leaders can never take tenure for granted. Political survival must be actively pursued by manipulating public policy to construct supporting coalition. Proposition 13: More divisions or cleavages of race, language, and religion in society increase instability. Therefore, the leader who is in the more homogeneous society is more likely to stay in office longer since the society is more likely to be stable. Ethnic, linguistic, and religious differences are inescapable facets of politics within as well as between countries; internal conflict and instability flow from tensions and processes of mobilization. In deeply divided societies (Lorwin, 197; Nordlinger, 1972), increased political consciousness, as the result of social mobilization, could be expected to strain or destroy the cohesion of states (Deutsch, 1961). The homogeneity index implies a measurement for social and political cleavages. As cleavages increase, so does political instability. A lack of homogeneity in the population contributes to increased political violence, i.e., political instability. If all population had the same political choices, the task of political job would be much easier. Where social cleavages are deep, the legitimacy of the social arrangements is low, and leadership is less likely to emerge unchallenged. Political cleavages result from a set of attitudes that divides the nation’s citizens into major political groups based on religion, language, race and tribe. Those cleavages represent a sense of distance between factions and causes fear, distrust, and hostility between them. It becomes the source of major conflict and leads to low integration. To that extent, loyalty to country or a head of government itself is dispersed. Political tensions and conflicts arising from social cleavages can seriously affect national 71 political instability and the capacity of governments to control their territories. As a result, the greater the homogeneity in a society, the more executive stability given the problem of issue bargainability. In a democratic society - religio-ethno-linguistically homogeneous - or alternately which provides a great deal of economic mobility - large degrees of economic inequality will be tolerated. Proposition 14: As one of the social mobilization indicators, a higher literacy rate results in a higher level of political stability, and, therefore, the leaders in that society stay in office for a long period. Countries with modernized social structures and developed, industrial economies are expected to have a higher level of stable and effective government, for the indicators of modernization, urbanization and literacy rate are important (Lerner, 1957; Lipset, 1960; Deutsch, 1961). An urban and industrial society makes democracy possible by providing a fair distribution of wealth, a public with a sense of political efficacy and the time and inclination to participate in politics. Literacy and urbanization pertain to a development away from a life of local isolation, traditionalism and political apathy, and into a different life of broader and deeper involvement in the vast complexities of modern life, including potential and actual involvement in mass politics. However, urbanization is not included in the test since it may be highly cerrelated with populated density. The literacy rate is indicative of the level of aspirations and expectations in society. It broadens outlooks, increases tolerance, reduces extremism, enhances belief in democratic values and practices, develops a capacity to make rational electoral choices, and reflects greater skills and specialization (Lipset, 1960). Greater literacy 72 promotes openness and a deeper insight into political issues and contributes to increased participation. The literacy rate, by specifying the proportion of population which can read in one language, gives a fair picture of national participation in the whole cultural sector. According to Lerner (1957), literacy around the world correlated at .84 with per-capita income and at .87 with industrialization. Proposition 15: Leaders in the countries with high levels of freedom status are more likely to have longer durations in office. As far as a definition of democracy can be incorporated into a concept of stability or institutionalization, which refers to the degree to which the political system may be expected to remain in existence, political democracy is associated with freedom of the individual. The degree of repressiveness imposed by a government indicates not only the extent to which a system of governance will tolerate its political challengers, but the plan of a coercive compliance structure. Political freedom is a combined index that political right and civil right indices that are measured by a govemment’s regulations which deprive basic human and political rights. If a society does not assure a degree of equality and participation, pressures that may undermine stability can be generated. The cost factor of political participation is directly linked to the extent of a govemment’s coercive activities, that is, the probability of getting caught as well as the severity of punishment. In a nondemocratic nation, that is to say, a nation with low political rights and civil rights, even though it is more likely to be unstable, the leaders can hold power long since the government sanction is too extreme and the cost of participation is too 73 high. However, sometimes there have been exceptions: for example, Pol Pot in Cambodia, Amin in Uganda, Marcias in Equatorial Guinea, and Bokassa in Central Africa, all ignored social and economic policy-making because they were able to avoid pressure for social and economic development only if the aspiration of their citizens were extremely low (Blondel, 1987, p.71). Nonetheless, even in a society with high political and civil right indices, where political institutions are relatively weak, leaders also can not stay longer, because the cost of participation is low and leadership is more likely to be vulnerable. The leaders in the society have less political power over the nonleaders. It increases the likelihood of political instability by exacerbating political divisions and conflicts and by encouraging criticism of the incumbent regime. Proposition 16: A presidential system based on elections has a longer duration of office than prime ministers through selection systems. In general, presidential systems are more stable - as measured by the tenure of the chief executive - than prime minister systems. The greater and more autonomous presidential resources make such stability likely. The basic constitutional rules by which political leaders are chosen and authoritative decisions are made should be considered. They can be operationalized by systems of executive leadership or institution of the executive. It explains the executive-legislative relations how independent a chief executive is from congress. Even though the position of prime ministers or general secretaries as collegial leadership is not as strong as the position of the president, they are still the most prominent figure in certain ways. Selection results in nomination to office, while election results in the holding of office. Prime ministers are less personality-oriented 74 and less focused on public image. In collegial leadership, the members of party or the members of politburo elect a top executive. Proposition 17: Cultural patterns based on regional differences, once established, possess considerable autonomy and can influence subsequent political and economic events, i.e., democracy (regime type) and economic development. Political culture plays an important role in the development and maintenance (or failure) of democracy. Based on regional comparisons, cultural difference should be considered as a control variable. Countries which have a common culture can be categorized, and these categories used in comparisons will then be likely to carry the same or similar meanings in each political system, such as Latin America, Europe, Asia, Oceania, the Arab Middle East, and Africa. Each political culture, as well as each region of the world differs somewhat in the typical backgrounds of its rulers. Political culture refers to widespread ideas, habits, norms, symbols, and practices that are politically relevant to a given system, especially as they relate to the legitimate use of power. Since the traditional culture of the period stressed obedience, respect, and deference to authority, there was a tacit general acceptance of the principle of government by men rather than laws. Alongside legitimation based on public consent, there are vestigial expectations about political leadership which are derived from the mixed Western heritage of monarchy, aristocracy, and the like. For example, while the path to democracy in EurOpe and the Anglo-American nations that were protestant resulted in higher levels of economic development and stabilization of democratic government, Asian countries followed Confucianism as an alternative road to democratization (Diamond, 1993). 75 However, one would hardly expect to find either democratic cultures or stable representative, liberal, constitutional regimes in Latin America or Africa. Without the Protestant tradition, there are likely to be unstable or perhaps ephemeral. The authoritarian, hierarchical, monistic cultural heritage. of Latin America has greatly diminished the prospects for liberal democracy (Inglehart, 1990). If there were cultural differences in the perception of political leaders and leadership, then one might reasonably anticipate that the cross-cultural validity of the findings associated with research on implicit leadership theory would be affected. Different cultural values affect the acceptability of ideas and practices associated with political leadership across the nations. Dispositions toward authority are different in each political culture. Western democratic political culture denies faith in powerful leaders, that is, authoritarian personalities, while common tendencies in Asia are more focused on loyalty to the collectivity over individual freedom and needs as well as on respect for paternalistic authority relations (Pye, 1984, pp.184-185). Even after the independence from a colonial control, cultural renewal is first and foremost the job of top political leadership. Cultural values should be exemplified by top leaders to provide supreme examples for others to follow. CHAPTER IV Operationalization and Methodology In the theoretical parts in the previous chapter, 17 propositions relating to a leader’s political survival were presented. In this chapter, first of all, data collection and sample selection will be discussed. Second, all independent variables and a dependent variable for testing the 17 hypotheses will be discussed and operationalized. Finally, with those operationalized variables, the most appropriate method for the research and its interpretation will be introduced and discussed. A. Data Collection and Operationalization Nation states arise from the time that they achieved independence as sovereign political units. The victory of the democracies in 1945 seemed to open a new era for political progress, with the United Nations as the symbol of the optimism. Between 1945 and 1991, almost 98 former dependencies joined the ranks of independent actors on the world stage. Nonetheless, of the approximately 175 independent countries that exist in the world today, more than 130 governments can be considered nondemocratic. The popular political system, that is, presidential or parliamentary, can not be applied to all independent countries. The large majority of third world countries function under a system which does not fall within the province of these two systems of government, and, definitely, communist countries operate under quite a different model. In modern constitutional regimes, a chief executive is chosen through each constitutive system. Some become presidents by referendum in general elections, some 76 77 by national assemblies, or some by coups or violence. Along similar lines, the communist leaders, i.e., the General Secretaries, are elected by the party in a one-party system, whereas the prime ministers also would be the heads of the government by the elected assembly or by a chairman of the party in the parliamentary system. Data Collection The sample in this research is composed of the political leaders who actually had been heads of government from 1945 to the end of 1991. 997 leaders from 147 countries including those who were still in power in 1991 when the data were collected are included. Among all the heads, the role of a head of government is most important in decision-making. As mentioned earlier, since ruling monarchs have gradually shrunk since World War 11, those are excluded from the samples. Also, all collective regimes are eliminated.9 However, even stop-gap, interim leaders, who are the truly temporary appointment of men chosen because they hold a neutral position in the political spectrum, are included in the sample. They usually would continue to be in these offices since they used to be vice presidents or deputy prime ministers before getting into interim positions. Considering both left and right time limits, some manipulations for data selection are needed. If a leader had entered his office before 1945 and got out of his office before 1992, he or she is included in the sample. However, although a leader became a head of government during that period and was still in power, it is not certain whether he can not be included in a target sample for the analyses since it is not possible to 9 See p.43 in CHAPTER II. 78 Figure 2 Distribution of Duration (Percentage) (x) 25 All Leaders C997) 20 Leaders out of Office (882) 15 Leaders In Office (11S) 10 5 0 14411le 0 2 4 6 B 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 4O 42 44 Duration (Years) Figure 3 Cases Excluded from the Sample Excluded from the sample Total cases are 13. .— lnciuded In the anaIySlS m- 1945 1989 1990 1991 1992 79 know his exit mode and correct duration of office. The plot of the frequency distribution of durations seems to be an exponential specification showing that it reveals a large concentration of shorter durations with the numbers of cases diminishing as durations become more lengthy (see Figure 2); high percentages of the distributions of 0-2 years exist in all leaders as well as the leaders out of office. In order to reduce missing data that represents the duration of leaders (115 leaders) who were still in office, 13 leaders who were in the duration of 0-2 years are deleted from the whole population. In other words, the leaders excluded from the sample are those who got into office since 1989 but just had been in office for less than 3 years. The leaders who were still in office, but had been in power longer than 2 years will be included in the statistical analyses (102 cases). Although longevity of a top executive has been theoretically explained by governmental stability or durability, it is, in a direct sense, a matter of personal survival, not governmental durability. To measure the length of his service is to measure the length of time that any one person holds office at a single stretch. Therefore, discontinuous terms of each individual leader are counted separately. Similarly, each regime of a country can be taken as a separate historical instance, i.e., as an individual case. When a national election is held, if an incumbent is reelected, the government is assumed to be the same government as the previous one. However, if a same leader became a top executive not in a consecutive terms, he is coded as a different case. There is nothing inherent in nonquantitative methods of political analysis that would prevent their application to the study of political leadership. The discovery or neglect of political leadership as a subject for political inquiry could not be attributed 80 primarily to the presence or absence of a commitment to quantitative scientific methods. New methods and facilities for collecting quantifiable data have provided scholars with an unexpected amount of information in the area of leadership research in part as well as in the modern societies. However, its selection of data has to be based on a previously established general theory. It should keep an eye on not only the problems of relevancy, but also the problems of validity. In fact, the problems of conceptualization and Operationalization are not easy. In most research on political leadership, biographies have been regarded as the main data sources. A political biography is a case history which should move us toward comparative generalizations about the success or failure of similar individuals in different situations and different individuals in similar situations (Edinger, 1964, p.671). However, the use of the biography is vulnerable to scholarly criticism. For example, according to Sidney Lee (1928): ....True biography is no handmaid of eternal instruction. Its purpose is not that of history. It does not exist to serve biological or anthropological science. Any assistance that biography renders these three great interests - ethical, historical, and scientific - should be accidental; such aid is neither essential nor obligatory. Subjectivity of biographical use results from several aspects. First, unsuccessful leaders tend to be slighted, because material on their lives is frequently far less readily available than it is for their more successful rivals. Second, the operational criteria seem to be determined as much by the author’s personal inclination as by the cultural climate in which he writes. Most political biographies have collected information from several sources. The 81 directories with short articles on each man are more inclusive in their coverage but contain only a minimum of information. The best sourCe of information about the lives of political leaders is the popular biography. The daily, weekly, and monthly press both in the United States and abroad contains a tremendous amount of biographical information. Some popular biography is indexed and readily available to the researchers. Also, although not all materials are indexed, some biographical information is most available in newspaper obituary columns. Since the evaluation of their performance is different, their backgrounds might not be recorded in an objective manner. Even though the use of a number of different sources yields conflicting facts and conclusions, those are, in fact, minor problems. Rather, political biographies have tended to fall into certain categories which are marked by how much significance is attributed to the subject’s personality or to his socio-political environment. The creative or literary biography is more deliberate in the selection and organization of data. The data on personal background and skills and personality of the political leaders can be collected from several kinds of sourcebooks (see APPENDIX A). For example, a Who ’s Who type of source is descriptive material about the incumbents of elite positions from which the more comparative studies attempt some sort of configurative analysis of elite attitudes and behavior. The gathering of social background data on political leaders should go hand in hand with the examination of the historical, situational, social, and psychological conditions under which they have emerged. These endeavors involve close scrutiny of primary and secondary sources 82 with heavy reliance on biographical materials, obituaries, and historical dictionaries, to the extent that these are available. ngrationalization In a strict sense, the duration of political office as a head of government takes place within an institutional framework which is determined in principle. Even though it is determined by an institutional or structural (constitutional) aspect, in the behavioral aspect, it is dependent on the effectiveness or performance of political leaders. It provides a test of the extent to which the arrangements are applied in practice and of the indication of the strength and authority of both the chief executives and of the political system. And, it suggests whether certain types of arrangement are generally more successful than others. The duration of chief executives in office is the most single important characteristic for evaluating their survival or success; it relates in part to the structures of the office itself, as some forms of government restrict the period during which the chief executive can stay in office. At least, we can compare the characteristics of the leaders who have succeeded in staying in office for one or more decades with those of ’ordinary’ heads of government in terms of their social and career background and their environment. In measuring a duration of office, if the duration is less than 6 months, it is counted as 0, and whenever the duration includes more than 6 months with some whole years, it is rounded off to a year. As a result, the unit of measurement is ’year’. So, it is possible to obtain information on the composition and duration of the political leaders and, thus, have a clearer picture of the event and type of experiences 83 which are shared by the rulers of different countries. Qualitative data on the backgrounds of political leaders can provide information about their origins and experiences. Biographical or historical materials are usually quantified as nominal, ordinal, interval, and ratio scales. A nominal scale, however, does not properly involve a quantitative dimension, since its numbers serve only to identify qualitatively distinct entities. The social background variables such as age, birth place, and educational level, as well as the career variables such as political experience, previous occupation, foreign experience, and party ideology, will be tested for the hypotheses. Profiles of political leaders do not yield any common threads. Institutional settings are so dissimilar that we are unable to formulate a set of common assumptions that apply to every situation. There are no precise solutions to a process that seems to be based on the personality of the individual, the collective culture of a group, and the situation at hand. Keeping attention to the question "who should rule?", it is important to think about what principle of selectivity should be used to choose political leaders. Who becomes a political leader is not just decided by elections, primaries, and voting but, rather, is also the result of a continual sifting and sorting of the citizens who enter the quest for political power. Furthermore, there are many examples to show how the conditions and requisites for entry into the political class vary from country to country and in different historical periods: Wealth, birth, and individual merit. The social background study provides possibilities to salvage the postulate of class interest by applying it not to individuals but to large numbers. It is also possible to shift the emphasis from the social or class origins of political leaders to their 84 education, training, and other formative experiences. Comparisons over time and among countries can greatly help in the formulation of such suggestions and hypotheses. The variables in this group are mostly personal backgrounds, that is, social background variables and career variables. These are very influential to political orientation on each area. For examples, family socialization depends on the social status of their fathers, the occupation of their fathers, and the place of birth. School socialization depends on educational backgrounds, major at schools and involvement in activities at school. Other sources for political orientation are traveling abroad, career attributes and military experiences, etc. Age, gender, and residence often have as great an influence on political opportunities as the class structure. The strength of a leader depends on various characteristics of a purely ’personal’ character. A political leader is almost always possessed of some set of philosophical and political convictions that he has, for one reason or another, made his own. As much might be said of almost every political leader who makes any pretense at ideological sophistication. For the most part in the studies of political leadership (psychological approaches), traits have been based on the (often expressed) assumption that the same skills and traits are required to be leader in all situations and circumstances. Desire, skill, and endurance are most necessary to succeed in a political career before someone can expect to be a political leader. Some ad hoc procedures definitely will be necessary to estimate the values of the explanatory variables at the times of events. For the institutional or country data, the time when the leaders became heads of government should be considered carefully. 85 On the other hand, some country variables such as population density, urbanization, literacy, freedom index, etc., are considered as time varying, others, such as country size, cabinet size, party system, economic system, homogeneity index, etc., are relatively constant or the same over time. Time varying variables are usually measured at the year when the leaders became chief executives. The sources of data collection and all variable lists for the research are in APPENDIX A. B. Methodology Statistical Analysis When all units are in the data set and all explanatory variables are observed, yet some values of the dependent variable are unobserved, those unobserved cases are censored intentionally. To drop the censored observations from the analysis is not only to discard useful information, but also to create predictable biases. Thus, in an effort to minimize the missing specification errors as much as possible, manipulation for data selection was introduced earlier in this chapter. Also, if the dependent variable (Y), duration of office, is considered as a continuous variable, a linear regression model may be possible. However, for certain theoretical purposes, the dependent variable is divided into 4 categories, and if it is limited in some way, the bias that arises from using least squares becomes a serious problem. Using regression estimates with a qualitative dependent variable can lead to serious errors in inference (Aldrich and Nelson, 1984, p.9). The least squares criterion is inapprbpriate or difficult to apply, since it can not easily be applied to variables that are ordinal or categorical in nature. 86 As seen in the previous theoretical part, a theoretical model was introduced based on ’duration of office’ as a dependent variable and three groups of exogenous variables, such as social, career backgrounds, and institutional characteristics, that included up to 27 dummy variables and 5 continuous variables (see Table 1). Thus, the analyses at first, will be preceded by three reduced models in order to test how each exogenous variable group relates with a dependent variable, and finally, by a grand model to examine the interactive effects of social and career backgrounds as well as the institutional characteristics. Based on the individual unit of analysis, a theoretical model with ’duration of office’ will be tested by a two-equation model that comprises a selection model equation including 984 cases with a two-category dependent variable, and a substantive model which will be applied to only 581 cases which are selected as a ’NON-SHORT’ category of the dependent variable, ’SURVIVAL’, in order to test the strength of political survival. The data for this research, as was mentioned above, are not from a random sample. Instead, the research attempts to examine the entire population of relevant data for the theoretical perspective, and, therefore, the violation of one of the assumption underlying a nonlinear probability model (probit or ordered probit) should not be a concern. Probit parameters are estimated by a method called Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE). MLE is different from OLS in that it does not have unbiasedness, efficiency, and normality with a small sample. However, in the case of large sample, it exhibits the asymptotic properties of unbiasedness, efficiency and normality. The main goal in using a two-equation model is based on stochastic censoring. The two- 87 equation model is specified as a probit in the selection equation and an ordered probit in the substantive equation. Selection Equation: As a dependent variable, SURVIVAL (Y,,) is a binary variable. A probit model is appropriate for a test using a dichotomous dependent variable based on the Bernoulli distribution. Yli has two values (0,1) and there will be only one threshold (u=0). Yli = 0!. + 251:in + “i ui~ N“), 521) YIi = { 0 (SHORT) if 0 5 duration 5 2 1 (NOT-SHORT) if durationz 3 . Unobserved theoretical dependent variable, Yi', satisfies Yi. = :kaki + ui “i” N(Oa 521) where the independent variables (Xis) are as followings (See Table 1): xI = AGE x, = POLTWO xl7 = CONSERV x,, = PARTFREE x2 = COLLEGE xlo = POLALL x., = OLD x,, = FULLFREE x, = URBAN xII = FORSTUD x., = PREZ x,., = ECONFREE x, = LAWPOL XI, = FORWORK x20 = SINGLEP x,, = ASIA x, = CIVSERV x., = FORBOTH x,. = MULTIP x2, = AFRICA x, = MILITAR x., = NCONSTI x2, = HOMOGEN x,o = MIDEAST x, = LIBTECH ‘ x,, = LIBERAL x,, = POPDEN x,l = EURNAME x, = POLONE x,, = CENTRE x,, = LITERACY x,2 = LATIN . In this formulation, the function of probability of getting value Yn = 1 (NOT-SHORT) is the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of the random variable Y,’. 88 P(Yli = 1) = P(Yi. > 0) = P(ui > 'szin) = P(ui < zflkxki) = P(ui < Zr) = F(Zi) Zi 1 J 8.8/2 dt = V21t of!) To obtain an estimate of the index Z,, the inverse of the cumulative normal distribution function, F“(P,), can be applied. The selection equation with a two-stage procedure is to estimate the probit function determining whether a leader stayed in office ’SHORT (Y,,=0)’ or ’NOT-SHORT (Y,,=l)’. Basically, for this function, we need to assume that we observe Y2, (STRENGTH of survival) when Y,,> 0. The main goal of this function is to get a value of A, (hazard rate) for each observation in a substantive equation, which comes from the sample selection procedure. Using the selection equation, we get an estimated value of Z,=-BX, for every case and calculate a hazard rate (A,) by ¢(Z,) / l - pl) & (p2 2 p3)] Prediction = 3 if [(p3 > pl) & (p3 > p2)] ’2 Reduction of Error (ROE) is calculated by the following formula: % correctly predicted - % modal 0 = ROE (A) 100 x 100 - % modal 96 is described by how well one can make predictions about the values for members on one variable based on their values on the other variable. The measure is defined as the proportion of errors reduced made, when information on the independent variable is used instead of ignored in making the predictions. Thus, the magnitude of measure of association may be interpreted as the proportional reduction in error. An error consists of a misclassification of a member on the dependent variable. The larger the relative reduction in error, the better the dependent variable can be predicted using the independent variable and the stronger the association between the variables. Descriptive Analysis First of all, in order to find what the similarities and differences between political leaders as heads of government are, the definition of cleavage or heterogeneity or fragmentation Should be introduced. Especially, in regard to their social backgrounds, career backgrounds, and personality or skills, it is possible to compare the variation based on homogeneity scores. Homogeneity scores based on personal background characteristics will be compared by the groups that indicate systematic differences such as duration, type of removal, region, type of head of government, and number of entry. Although the sample is a nonrandom purposive sample of political leaders with possibilities as well as limitations, it is possible to develop, consistent with canons of contemporary social science, descriptive - historical statements - or "modal models" - of leader traits and skills, and their social and career backgrounds. In order to make the data from diverse cultures and time periods functionally equivalent, the information of ethnocentric or otherwise biased materials must be minimized as much as possible. 97 The sample (882) representing the leaders who are out of office is used for the analyses with duration of office and type of removal, whereas the whole sample (997) including the present leaders, is used for the other analyses such as region, type of head of government, or number of entry. It is based on the descriptive statistical method of summarizing the information through crosstabulations. Some variables used in the descriptive analysis are collapsed into different categories for different purposes. Rae and Taylor (1970, pp.26-33) introduced how to measure the homogeneity index. However, Kim and Patterson (1991, p.198) modified Rae’s formula for the fragmentation score, Since different background characteristics are coded in different numbers of categories and it is impossible to compare the scores across variables. Especially with a data set which includes several missing values in some variables”, a certain effort is needed to utilize available data without discarding all cases with missing cases values. Some social background variables, such as SES and father’s A occupation, have been omitted from the inferential models because those variables have higher percentages of missing cases. However, they are included in the descriptive analyses as important elements. Considering that the cases are divided equally between 11 categories", the '3 In this study, some personal variables have relatively high percentages of missing data: place of birth (7.9%), major (2.6%), SES (35.9%), father’s occupation (40.9%), and orals kills, organimtion skills, language skills, parents’ death/separation in early age, physical deformity, and power connection (22.3%). Also, there are some other personal variables that have small percentages of missing data such as age (.8%), education (1.0%), foreign experience (.9%), prison/exile experience, political activity, military experience, previous career (.8%), experience in congress (2.1%), experience in party (2.0%), experience in ministry (1.8%). In case of the institutional variables, homogeneity index (5.1%), party system (.2%), and literacy (1.0%) have missing values. " The range of F score is 0 to 1. If each individual is in a category by himself (N=n), the upper bound for F is 1. 98 formula for Rae’s fragmentation score should be modified. The measure of homogeneity score (H) = l - F', where F’” is the adjusted fragmentation score. For an example, if SES of the Asian leaders (114 cases) is divided into 3 categories [low (27), middle (23), high (64)], Fmam = 114 x (3 - 1) / (114 - 1) x 3 and F = (272 + 232 + 642) / 1142. As a result, the homogeneity score on SES of the Asian leaders is .123. Thus, when interpreting this score, it is not important what category has the highest or lowest frequencies. Rather, it just indicates how similar or different the leaders in a certain group are on a certain variable. '5 F' = F/Fm, where F is Rae’s fragmentation score and Fm is the maximum score an index can attain given its number of categories. The formulas for F and F' are as follows: ._'_ N(N-l) PM = N(n - 1)/n(N-l) F=1- ism-1) CHAPTER V Presentation and Discussion of Results As discussed in Chapter III and Chapter IV, 984 top executives (heads of governments) across 147 countries were selected by some manipulation and 17 propositions were introduced. A two-equation model is composed of 32 independent 4 variables (5 continuous variables and 27 dummy variables). The dependent variable, ’duration in office’, is used according to two different perspectives. For the selection equations, it is categorized into either ’SHORT (0-2 years)’ or ’NOT-SHORT (3 + years)’. ’NOT-SHORT’ is coded as 1 (581 cases) and ’SHORT’ as 0 (403 cases). However, in the substantive equations, only ’NOT-SHORT’ (581 cases) is included for testing and analyzed as three different categories: 1 (3 - 6 years), 2 (7 - 12 years), and 3 (13 years + ). In this chapter, first of all, in order to test the propositions on social backgrounds, career backgrounds, and institutional variables, the results of each reduced model will be discussed. With the reduced models, it is predicted to see whether social, or career backgrounds, or institutional attributes as an individual subgroup is a valid predictor of political survival as political success. Second, an interaction model scrutinizes interactional effect after combining all three subgroups together. Being different from the results of the reduced models, it will present different explanation and prediction. Although the career background model (64.7%) among the reduced models indicates the best goodness-of-it for predicting political survival (Selection equation), the interaction model (66.55%) shows a better fit than others. Meanwhile, in case of 99 100 the substantive equation (the strength of political survival), the institutional model (64.65%) has the highest percentage correctly predicted, but the interaction model (64.74%) surpasses the institutional model (64.65%) in prediction by a shade of difference. Therefore, interpretations of the results from the interaction model will be more emphasized and examined according to each hypothesis. Finally, at the end of this chapter, the interaction model will be tested by regional differences. In the previous tests, the regional dummies do not Show any significance. Therefore, in order to see the regional effect, it is worth while dividing the sample into different regional groups and testing each interaction model. Even though Oceanic countries are excluded from the interpretation for the lack of enough cases, it is possible to find the preferences on political leaders in each region. Personal backgrounds have greater impact on political survival in Latin America in comparison with other regions. However, for explaining the strength of political survival, more personal background variables have significant impact in both the African model and the Middle Eastern model. According to the goodness-of-fit measures for the regional models, the Middle Eastern model (83.33% correctly predicted) explains leaders’ duration, short or long, whereas the European model shows the lowest fit (67.69%). In contrast, for the strength of political survival, the African model (53.61%) indicates the lowest fit and the Middle Eastern (83.97%) and Latin American (87.16%) models indicate better fits than others. 101 A. Statistical Analysis of the Two-Equation Model Based on the theoretical propositions mentioned in Chapter III, variables are operationalized and tested for each hypothesis. The results from the OLS model, which is based on continuous duration data do not differ much from those in the substantive equation of the interaction model (see APPENDIX C). The independent variables that are significant in the OLS model are also significant in the ordered probit model. F reign experiences, ideology, and party system variables turn out to be different. While both SINGLE? and MULTIP are significant in the ordered probit, only MULTIP is Significant in the OLS model. In the OLS model, R2, the goodness-of-fit measure comes out to be .20 (corrected R2 is .17) which is not good enough. Except R2 statistics, there is nothing else to evaluate a model as a whole. Thus, as far as similar results on significance tests can be seen later in the ordered probit model, the OLS can not be interpreted in any other way. Therefore, this section presents the results of a two-equation model with both the selection (dichotomous probit) and the substantive equations (polychotomous ordered probit), which utilize the same operationalized variables as used in the OLS. In fact, before scrutinizing the whole model (Interaction model) itself, the results from each reduced model will be discussed step by step. Analysis on Social Backgrounds The results of both the selection (probit) and the substantive (ordered probit) equations, which estimate a dependent variable, SURVIVAL, with just social background variables, are given in Table 2. Both equations are composed of three independent 102 variables, but the substantive equation has one more exogenous variable, the hazard rate (A,), which is calculated from selection equation in order to adjust for selection bias. Selection Equation : SURVIVAL = a + B,AGE + BzCOLLEGE + BJURBAN + u, Substantive Equation : STRENGTH = a + [3,AGE + B,C0LLEGE + B,URBAN + haz + II, In the selection equation, whether the estimated R2 turns out to be significant or not, it is not used as a measure of goodness of fit. This model predicts 61.17% of the durations correctly. The model as a whole, using an analog to F-statistics, -2LLR, is easily significant at the .001 level with a value of 70.48. Nonetheless, actually, the substantive equation has a better fit than the selection equation since the percentage correctly predicted (62.12 %) and -2LLR (96.28) is higher in the substantive equation. In terms of the individual coefficients, all three of the social backgrounds are Significant: AGE and URBAN are significant at .05, and COLLEGE at .10. Surprisingly, however, the directions of URBAN and COLLEGE are different from the predicted ones. In other words, these three social background variables have significant relationships with whether leaders stay in office for ’SHORT’ or ’NOT-SHORT’, but, in fact, the leaders who had degrees above college and were born in urban areas less more likely to stay in office for longer periods. The negative sign and relatively weak significance of COLLEGE suggests that military education is considered as a category of above college, and that usually military 103 leaders are more likely to stay in office shorter because they are coup d’etat leaders, transitional or care-taker leaders. Even though URBAN has a significant effect on whether the leader stays in office for a short period or not, unexpectedly, the direction of the relationship turns out to be opposite. The greater chance to be exposed to politics and media in urban areas does not have any roles on political socialization. Table 2 Coefficient Estimates for Social Background Variables Selection Equation Substantive Equation Dependent Variable: SURVIVAL Dependent Variable: STRENGTH Variable MLE S.E. t-score Variable MLE S.E. t-score Constant 1.274 .247 5.167‘" Constant .017 .102 0.163 AGE -.112 .040 3029"" AGE .706 2.066 0.342 COLLEGE -.238 .131 -1.813 " COLLEGE .560 1.886 0.297 URBAN -.224 .086 -2.603"'" URBAN -7.960 20.228 -0.394 haz 5.814 1 1.965 0.486 It .764 .061 12.552‘“ % correctly predicted 61.17 % correctly predicted 62.12 -2 x LLR 70.48“" -2 x LLR 96.28"” N 904 N 557 " significant at .10 ” significant at .05 ”" significant at .01 With the data (581 cases) from the selection equation, the same independent variables are tested with three categories of duration (DURATION) in order to test the relationships between the social background variables and the strength of political survival. The most interesting finding is that all the exogenous variables are not significant in the substantive equation. Hence, those three social background variables 104 really matter with whether the leaders stay in office for a short time or not, but do not influence the strength of political survival at all beyond this point. i As a result, these social background variables are very important elements not for the leaders to hold their power longer, but for the people when they elect or choose their leaders. It suggests that after a certain period, i.e. a honeymoon period, the social backgrounds are not considered as significant requirements for the leaders’ maintenance in office. During the honeymoon period, the leaders with a peculiar blend of activism and inexperience, prepare to build up new policies and try to mount desires for innovation at precisely the time expertise is lacking as, a weapon for survival. Analysis on Career Backgrounds Selection Equation : SURVIVAL = a + [3,LAWPOL + 8,CIVSERv + B,MILITAR + p,LIBTECH + p,I>oLoNE + B6POLTWO + 8,I>oLALL + 8,I=oRSTUD + p,FonoRK + 8,,FoRBoTH + [3,,NCONSTI + 8,,LIBERAL + [3,,CEN'I'RE + [3,,CoNSERv + u, Substantive Equation : STRENGTH = or + B,LAWPOL + BZCIVSERV + p,MILITAR + 8,LIBTECH + BSPOLONE + 8,I>oLTwo + B,POLALL + B,F0RSTUD + B,I=onoRx + 8.,F0RB0TH + [3,,NCONSTI + 5.,LIBERAL + 8.,CENTRE + 8.,CoNSERv + haz + u, Among the previous occupations in which the leaders were involved, the politically related fields, such as lawyers, political activists, party officials, as well as civil servants (ministry jobs) have great impact on leaders’ political survival. Even though liberal occupation, technical business, etc. are significant at the .10 level (Table 3), military jObs are not crucial to decide their survival at all. However, contrary to the 105 theoretical expectations, the relationships between politically related jobs (LAWPOL and CIVSERV) and political survival are negative. Political experiences, whether they had experience only in party, ministry, or congress, are necessary requirements for the leaders to stay in office longer. The degree of political experience or its experience in some special places, in fact, does not matter, but the leaders should have at least some political experience. In case of foreign experiences, working in foreign countries itself does not have any impact on political survival. However, studying in foreign countries has significant role in deciding whether or not a leader stays in office for a shorter period. According to socialization theory, political socialization is more effective at schools than at work areas. Especially, most jobs in foreign countries are military attache, diplomatic mission, business, and so on. Thus, foreign experiences in those jobs would not have limited impact on new political socialization. However, when leaders were studying abroad, they would acquire certain political perspectives and develop their own views on politics. For example (see Figure 7), high percentages of leaders except in North American and European countries had foreign experience. This trend indicates that leaders from underdeveloped or developing countries would go to foreign countries to obtain advanced education and they have more opportunities to see all different aspects of politics in countries other than their own. As for the hypothesis on entry mode (NCONSTI), it is expected that leaders by nonconstitutional entry are more likely to stay shorter. However, the null hypothesis is not rejected, Since the t-score of NCONSTI is lower than its critical value, while means that nonconstitutional entry does not have any relationship with political survival at all. 106 Table 3 Coefficient Estimates for Career Background Variables Selection Equation Substantive Equation Dependent Variable: SURVIVAL Dependent Variable: STRENGTH Variable MLE S.E. t-score Variable MLE S.E. t-score Constant -0.335 0.347 -0.968 Constant 0.473 3.707 0.127 LAWPOL -0.598 0.246 -2.433” LAWPOL -1.171 2.494 -0.470 CIVSERV -0.600 0.267 2244" CIVSERV -1.459 2.504 -0.583 MILITAR -0.217 0.268 -0.811 MILITAR -0.608 0.987 -0.616 LIBTECH -0.445 . 0.243 -1.828"‘ LIBTECH -1.004 1.893 -0.530 POLONE 0.5 13 0.247 2.077" "' POLONE 0.509 1.725 0.295 POLTWO 0.643 0.269 2.390" POLTWO 0.504 2.260 0.223 POLALL 0.609 0.271 2.246" POLALL 0.408 2.118 0.193 FORSTUD 0.243 0.103 2.351 " FORSTUD 0.601 0.964 0.623 FORWORK 0.189 0.122 1 .554 FORWORK 0.323 0.769 0.420 FORBOTH 0.328 0.139 _ 2.350” FORBOTH 0.485 1.327 0.366 NCONSTI -0.101 0.131 -0.773 NCONST'I 0.320 0.428 0.748 LIBERAL 0.381 0.178 2.142" ‘ LIBERAL 0.747 1.490 0.501 CENTRE -0.046 0.233 -0.197 CENTRE 0.372 0.341 1.092 CONSERV 0.505 0.173 2921"“ CONSERV 0.939 1.991 0.472 haz -1.328 5.715 -0.232 p 0.734 0.058 12.636”* % correctly predicted 64.70 % correctly predicted 61.82 -2 x LLR 9840*” -2 x LLR 7334*" N 949 N 571 " significant at .10 ” significant at .05 “‘ significant at .01 107 With the exception of most military leaders, almost all leaders should represent their political ideologies in their elections or in their decision-making processes. The results Show that the leaders whose ideologies are liberal or conservative are more likely to stay in office longer. The direction of the relationship between LIBERAL and political survival is positive although it would be expected to be negative. Just as for the social background variables, all career background variables do not have any relationships with political survival in the substantive equation, supporting the previous argument that the same career backgrounds as personal attributes are significant in explaining political survival, i.e. , SHORT or NOTSHORT rather than the strength of political survival. In the case of career backgrounds being different from the social background variables, the selection equation (64.7 % correctly predicted and with - 2LLR (98.40)) shows a better fit than the substantive equation (61.82% correctly predicted and with -2LLR (73.34)). While the selection equation explains better in career backgrounds than in social backgrounds, the substantive equation has a better fit in social backgrounds. From these results, it is apparent that career backgrounds are more important in deciding whether a leader survives beyond a short period, but they do not affect how long the person stays in office after that initial test period. siso I ti i 1A 'b Selection Equation: SURVIVAL = a + B,OLD + 13sz + 8,SINGLEI> + B,MULTIP + BSHOMOGEN + B,PoI>DEN + B,LITERACY + 8,I>ARTFREE + 8,FULLFREE + 8,,EC0NFREE + [3,,ASIA + 8,,AFRICA + B,,MIDEAST + BMEURNAME + p,,LATIN + u, l 08 Substantive Equation: STRENGTH = a + B,OLD + mm + I3,SINGLEI> + [34MULTIP + 8,H0M0GEN + [36POPDEN + B,LITERACY + B,PARTFREE + B,FULLEREE + 8.,EC0NFREE + [3,,ASIA + 8.,AFRICA + B,,MIDEAST + [3,,EURNAME + B,,LATIN + haz + It, Again, the independent variables that turn out to be significant in the selection equation become insignificant in the substantive equation. Like personal variables (social and career), institutional variables do not explain the strength of political survival, although some of them are significant in deciding whether leaders stay in office for a short period or not. Country age (OLD) is an important element for political survival and its direction of the relationship is expected to be positive, but it comes out negative. Thus, leaders in older countries are more likely to stay only a short time in office. As far as political stability and tranquility are concerned, the leader in old countries can maintain his power longer. Nonetheless, while European and North American countries have stable liberal parliamentary democracies, and Latin American countries often have had military regimes, those political sytems which lead to frequent leadership succession. Meanwhile, African countries and several Asian countries are young, having only been independent since the 19605. If a leader was a founder or a first leader in those countries, they were often top leaders for a long time until their new political regimes become stable or developed in a certain degree. Presidential system (PREZ) supports leaders to stay longer than parliamentary systems (and general secretaries). Presidential systems guarantee constitutional terms (4-6 yrs). Under prime minister systems, top executives confront elections whenever 109 Table 4 Coefficient Estimates for Institutional Attributes Selection Equation Substantive Equation Dependent Variable: SURVIVAL Dependent Variable: STRENGTH Variable MLE S.E. t-score Variable MLE S.E. t—score Constant -0.195 0.381 -0.51 1 Constant 2.331 2.756 0.846 OLD -0.264 0.124 -2.134” OLD -0.989 0.772 -1.280 PREZ 0.589 0.124 4.763” PREZ 1.369 1.755 0.780 SINGLEP 0.388 0.186 2.089” SINGLEP 1.233 1.187 1.039 MULTIP -0.055 0.167 -0.327 MULTIP -0.344 0.253 -1.359 HOMOGEN -7.5e-05 2.3 e-04 -0.33 1 HOMOGEN -2.7e—4 3.1e-4 -0.858 POPDEN -7.8e-05 2.8e-04 -0.282 POPDEN 2.2e-4 3.8e-4 0.596 LITERACY 0.008 0.024 3.246‘” LITERACY 0.020 0.230 0.872 PARTFREE 0.139 0.157 0.885 PARTFREE 0.228 0.459 0.497 FULLFREE 0.737 0.209 3530“" FULLFREE 1.127 2.189 0.515 ECONFREE -0. l 35 0.060 -2.245’ "‘ ECONF REE _ -0.279 0.399 -0.700 ASIA 0.041 0.265 0.156 ASIA -0.092 0.332 -0.276 AFRICA 0.037 0.276 0.133 AFRICA 0.086 0.327 0.262 MIDEAST -0.166 0.269 -0.617 MIDEAST -0.583 0.593 -0.983 EURNAME -0.278 0.235 -l.182 EURNAME -0.630 0.892 -0.706 LATIN -0.23 1 0.251 -0.923 LATIN -1 .284 0.774 -1.658‘ haz -3.245 4.191 -0.774 p 0.843 0.666 12.649‘“ % correctly predicted 62.62 % correctly predicted 64.65 -2 x LLR 92.70"” -2 x LLR 165.44"“ N 947 N 563 " significant at .10 ” significant at .05 "* significant at .01 llO parliamentary members vote no confidence, sometimes as frequently as every other year. Even though general secretaries in communist countries are similar to prime ministers in terms of the selection process, they usually stay in office until their deaths. SINGLEP is significant at the .05 level and it supports the relationship between party system and political survival that we expected earlier, whereas MULTIP is not significant. Single-party systems are stable only in the formal sense that a single party remains in power for decades. The impact of parties is considered as strengthening the link between rulers and the population. However, although it is believed that some countries are officially based on multiparty systems, only one party always takes the initiative in politics. In this case, the party system should be considered as a monopolized one-party system in reality. In order to have better outcomes from this model, more careful inspections of party systems are required. One of the most unexpected results is generated from HOMOGEN and POPDEN, which fail to support our expectations about relationship between political stability and leadership durability. The indicators of govemability, the homogeneity index and the population density were expected to be significant on political stability, and, ultimately, on the leader’s durability. Unexpectedly, however, there are no relationships between political survival and any of them. Considering on the freedom status, not only in political and civil rights but also in economic field, FULLFREE and ECONFREE are proven to be significant. While freer societies, in the terms of political and civil rights, allow their leaders to stay longer, high economic freedom (ECONFREE) has a role against the leaders’ longevity. If officials employ force, that fact directly reflects a loss of power regardless of any legal 111 justification that those officials are able to invoke. As a result, those who rely primarily on force are likely to be politically unsuccessful, whether or not they assumed office through a military coup. Successful regimes, military or otherwise, are those that are capable of exercising power. The repeated invocation of force is evidence of a loss of power and it accrues to the level of freedom guaranteed. Meanwhile, the economy with high level of freedom is inherently unstable; economic growth is constantly disrupted by crises. In a country with low economic freedom, intervention in the economy and other Spheres grows and draws attention to the issues of choice, planning and control. 80, the ’hand of the state’ is more visible and intelligible than ’the invisible hand’ of the market. Consequently, as long as the governments take on responsibility for more and more areas of the economy, governments can avoid economic and political crises and finally leaders would keep their offices longer. Regional difference as a control variable, in effect, does not show any significance in explaining political survival. However, in the substantive equation, only LATIN is significant at the .10 level. Furthermore, it has a negative relationship to the strength of survival, indicating that the level of longevity can be explained better in Latin America, and that the Latin American leaders are more likely to stay in office shorter. Apparently, in Latin America, we see quite a few leaders who just stayed in office as coup d’etat leaders for a short period or were themselves overthrown again by the military. Also, by constitution, several countries in this area do not allow the same leaders to be elected in a consecutive term or their tenure is limited to a certain period (see note 6). 112 In general, the statistics for testing a whole model with the institutional attributes Show the same tendencies as shown in the previous social and career background models. The independent variables that are significant in the selection equation become insignificant in the substantive equation (Table 4). Both the selection and substantive equations, as a whole, are significant at the .01 level. However, the substantive equation (64.65 %) has a higher proportion of prediction than the selection equation (62.62%). The institutional model itself explains the strength of political survival better than political survival. Comparisons of the Reduced Models on Political Survival Analyses of the success tables generated from the results are presented only for explaining political survival. In principle, those success tables of the strength of political survival (substantive equations) should be 3 x 3 tables, but the results show 3 x 2 tables because the models do not predict the second category (7 - 12 years). Thus, it is not reasonable to compare the predictions for the substantive equations. Also, in order to use the statistics, i.e. , ROE (Reduction of Error), it is better to focus on 2 x 2 tables, that is, the success tables in the selection equations. In Table 5, it is possible to see how the composition of the success of prediction is composed of. In the case of the social background model, the category of SHORT has a big reduction, 31.8% (38.4% - 6.6%) and NOTSHORT has a big improvement, 33.6% (61.6% -r 95.2%). In the case of the career background model, the SHORT category shows a 13.9% of reduction of prediction, while NOTSHORT is improved by 30.2%. Moreover, the institutional model indicates an 11.1% reduction in predicting SHORT, and PREDICT PREDICT PREDICT 113 Social Backgrounds Table 5 Success of Prediction in Political Survival ACTUAL 0 1 Row SHORT NOT-SHORT TOTAL 0 23 27 so SHORT 6.6 4.8 5.5 1 324 530 854 NOT SHORT 93.4 95.2 94.5 COLUMN 347 557 904 TOTAL 38.4 61.6 100.0 Career Backgrounds ACTUAL 0 1 Row SHORT NOT-SHORT TOTAL 0 98 55 153 SHORT 25.9 9.6 16.1 1 280 516 796 NOT-SHORT 74.1 90.4 83.9 COLUMN 378 571 949 TOTAL 39.8 60.2 100.0 Institutional Attributes ACTUAL 0 1 Row SHORT NOT-SHORT TOTAL 0 113 83 196 SHORT 29.4 14.7 20.7 1 271 480 751 NOT-SHORT 70.6 85.3 79.3 COLUMN 384 563 947 TOTAL 40.5 59.5 100.0 114 a 25.8% improvement in predicting NOTSHORT. As can be seen in each reduced table, and in Table 8, the career background model represents the best goodness-of-fit among the reduced models. Its proportion correctly predicted is 64.7% and ROE is 11.37. In other words, in order to explain political survival itself, it is better to use the career background model. However, in terms of only the percentage of correctly predicted, the institutional attribute model (64.65%) can predict the strength of political survival better than the other two models social background (62.12%) and career background (61.82%). Nonetheless, all two- equation reduced models have a common tendency: some variables that are significant in the selection equation lose their influence in the substantive equation. Analysis on Interaction Model Selection Equation: SURVIVAL = or + B,AGE + B,COLLEGE + 8,URBAN + 8,LAWI>OL + B,CIVSERV + 8,MILITAR + 8,LIBTECH + 8,POLONE + [39POLTWO + 8,,POLALL + [3,,FORSTUD + 8,,FORWORK + 8.,FORBOTH + [3,,NCONSTI + 8,,LIBERAL + [3,,CENTRE + 8,,CONSERV + B,,OLD + [3,,PREZ + [3,,SINGLEP + 0,,MULT'IP + 8,,HOMOGEN + [3,,POPDEN + [1,,LITERACY + 9,,PARTFREE + 8,,FULLFREE + 8,,ECONFREE + [3,,ASIA + 8,,AERICA + 8,,MIDEAST + 8,.EURNAME + 8,,LATIN + p, Substantive Equation: STRENGTH = a + [3,AGE + BZCOLLEGE + p,URBAN + p,LAWPOL + BSCIVSERV + p,MILITAR + B,LIBTECH + B,POLONE + p,POLTwo + [3,0POLALL + B,,FORSTUD + BUFORWORK + 8,,FORBOTH + 5,,NCONS'IT + [3,,LIBERAL + 8,,CENTRE + 13,,CONSERV + 8,,OLD + 8,,PREz + 8,,erGLEP + 8,,MULTIP + [1,,HOMOGEN + 8,,POPDEN + 8,,LITERACY + [3,,PARTFREE + 8,,FULLFREE + p,,ECONFREE + 8,,ASIA + 8,,AERICA + [3,,MIDEAST + [3,,EURNAME + 8,,LATIN + haz + p, In the case of the selection equation (Table 6), the results Show that AGE, 115 URBAN, CONSERV, PREZ, LITERACY, and ECONFREE are significant at the .05 level, and that COLLEGE, POLALL, LAWPOL, FORSTUD, FORBOTH, and PARTFREE are significant at the .10 level. Except NCONSTI, OLD, HOMOGEN, POPDEN, and regional dummies, at least one of the dummies in each variable turns out to be significant, supporting the relationships between these variables and political survival. As seen in the previous three reduced models, the directions of some variables are opposite to those expected (COLLEGE, URBAN, LAWPOL, and ECONFREE). Some differences will now be discussed based on the comparisons between selection and substantive equations, as well as between the reduced models and the interaction model. First of all, in the case of the selection equation, in comparison with the reduced models, the significance of CIVSERV, LIBTECH, POLONE, POLTWO, LIBERAL, OLD, and SINGLEP had disappeared. However, as shown in Table 8, the proportion correctly predicted (66.6%) is higher than those (61.17% for social backgrounds, 64.70% for career backgrounds, and 62.62% for institutional attributes) in each reduced model. Secondly, in the reduced substantive equations, all significant variables in the selected equations became insignificant in the substantive equations. Meanwhile, some variables stay the same and even new ones such as CIVSERV, LIBTECH, FORWORK, OLD, SINGLEP, and MULTIP become Significant in the substantive equation of the interaction model. Instead, the relationships of POLALL, PARTFREE, and ECONFREE with the strength of political survival have disappeared in the substantive equation. All social background variables, AGE, COLLEGE, and URBAN have great impact on both political survival and the strength of political survival, indicating the following 116 Table 6 Coefficient Estimates for Interaction Model Selection equation Substantive equation Dependent Variable: SURVIVAL Dependent Variable: STRENGTH Variable MLE S.E. t-score Variable MLE S.E. t-score Constant 0.300 0.598 0.503 Constant 6.005 2.703 2.221" AGE -0.014 0.005 2915‘” AGE -0.071 0.026 -2.7l8” COLLEGE -0.304 0.157 -1.935“' COLLEGE -1.050 0.570 -1.842"' URBAN -0.194 0.010 -2.004” URBAN -0.791 0.355 -2.228” LAWPOL -0.524 0.284 -1 .845“ LAWPOL -1.822 0.992 -1 .838‘ CIVSERV -0.459 0.307 -1.495 CIVSERV -2.226 0.925 -2.407" "' " MILITAR -0.063 0.309 -0.205 MILITAR -0.249 0.321 -0.777 LIBTECH -0.364 0.278 -1.308 LIBTECH -1.453 0.722 -2.01 1” POLONE 0.369 0.292 1.264 POLONE 0.985 0.710 1.387 POLTWO 0.499 0.309 1.614 POLTWO 1.244 0.921 1.350 POLALL 0.591 0.312 1.894‘ POLALL 1.515 1.066 1.421 F ORSTUD 0.232 0.120 1.930" FORSTUD 1.085 0.443 2.449‘ ‘ FORWORK 0.083 0.136 0.613 FORWORK 0.484 0.237 2.037‘ ‘ FORBOTH 0.275 0.154 1 .783 ‘ FORBOTH 1.077 0.520 2.072“ NCONSTI -0.151 0.156 -0.965 NCONSTI -0.431 0.3 32 -1.296 LIBERAL 0.270 0.209 1.292 LIBERAL 0.826 0.554 1.491 CENTRE -0.068 0.266 -0.255 CENTRE 0.187 0.396 0.471 CONSERV 0.477 0.200 2.384” CONSERV 1.768 0.900 1.963" OLD -0.2 10 0. 135 -1 .549 OLD -1 .003 0.402 -2.496" "' PREZ 0.694 0.138 5041*” PREZ 2.194 1.265 1.735" SINGLEP 0.083 0.243 0.341 SINGLEP 0.865 0.352 2.457" MULTIP -0.260 0.222 - 1 . 169 MULTIP -0.933 0.547 -1.707" HOMOGEN 9.7e-05 2.7e-04 0.356 HOMOGEN 1 .6e-04 3 .5e-04 0.466 POPDEN -6.5e-06 3 .0e-04 -0.022 POPDEN 4.2e-04 3.5e-04 1 .205 LITERACY 0.007 0.003 2.659" LITERACY 0.027 0.013 2.025“I PARTFREE 0.073 0.1 77 0.41 1 PARTFREE 0.305 0.246 1 .243 EU LLF REE 0.73 1 0.242 3.027 " "‘ * FULLFREE 1 .956 1.367 1.43 1 ECONFREE -0.115 0.696 -1.654" ECONFREE -0.366 0.225 -1.622 ASIA 0.31 1 0.295 1.054 ASIA 0.774 0.632 1.225 AFRICA 0.105 0.306 0.343 AFRICA 0.152 0.376 0.404 MIDEAST -0.019 0.294 -0.064 MIDEAST -0.342 0.346 -0.988 EURNAME 0.014 0.257 0.055 EURNAME 0.101 0.300 0.338 LATIN 0.174 0.281 0.617 LATIN -0.374 0.428 ‘ -0.874 haz -4.258 2.503 -1.701" p 0.905 0.073 12.441 "" % correctly predicted 66.55 % correctly predicted 64.74 -2 x LLR 165.20“" -2 x LLR 207.52‘" N 861 N 536 " significant at .10 ” significant at .05 ""' significant at .01 117 relationships: 1. The younger the leaders are upon entering Office, the longer they stay in office. 2. Leaders with more educations (above college) are less likely to stay in office longer. 3. Leaders who were born and raised in urban areas tend to stay in office shorter than those from rural areas. Among the career background variables in the selection equation, only entry mode (NCONSTI) does not have any influence on explaining the relationship with political survival, whereas, in accounting for the strength Of political survival, all political experiences as well as entry mode, regardless of what offices they had been in previously, do not explain the strength of political survival at all. On the contrary, foreign experiences strongly account for the relationships with the strength of political survival. Career background variables in the interaction model indicate somewhat different results. Actually, the results represents more obvious explanations from a theoretical perspective. Among the previous occupations, only LAWPOL is significant and, among the political experiences, only POLALL. The most interesting finding concerns leaders’ ideology. Whether a leader is liberal or conservative has a great impact on the leader’s political survival in the reduced model. However, in the interaction model, the outcome really supports the proposition that leftist (Liberal) parties tend to be more willing to change priorities than rightist ones, primarily because change is a more legitimate enterprise to the lefi than it is to the right. The relationships of career backgrounds to 118 political survival are explained as follows: 4. Except military professions, leaders with politically related occupations such as political activists, lawyers, party officials, civil servants, as well as even liberal and technical professions and business, are less likely tO stay in office longer. Meanwhile, in explaining political survival itself, only leaders who were lawyers or politicians before, are less likely to stay in office longer. 5. While a part of political experiences (POLALL) explains political survival, there are no relationships between political experiences and the strength of political survival. Especially, foreign study is very important for political survival. 6. Whatever the purpose of foreign experience is, they have great impact in accounting for the degree of political survival. 7. Entry mode does not matter with political survival or the strength of political survival. 8. With regard to the political ideology, conservative leaders are more likely . to stay in office longer. In terms of the coefficients for the institutional characteristics, it is apparent that there are several changes from the selection equation to the substantive equation. Country age in the reduced model (Institutional model) is significant, but, in the interaction model, it does not account for its relationship with political survival (t-score (=-1.549) is not large for being significant). However, it shows a strong significance in accounting for the strength Of political survival. Interestingly, the type of head of government (PREZ) is very important in determining whether or not a leader stays in Office for a short period. However, while still significant at the .10 level, it is not as strong as it is in explaining the length Of his survival after the initial period. Party system does not give an explanation of political survival itself (short or long), whereas it clearly proves the relationships with the strength of survival. With 119 respect to the Freedom index as a combination of political rights and civil rights, the leaders in fully free societies (FULLFREE) stay in office longer, but the strength of survival is not explained by it at all. In contrast, in countries where the governments guarantee more economic freedom, the leaders are less likely to stay in office longer. In the model for the strength of survival, even though its t-score is almost close to the significance level, it is not enough to explain the relationship. Finally, it is interesting to speculate that regional difference does not expound political survival itself as well as the degree of durability. As a result, the interaction model shows the following outcomes: 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. Leaders in Old countries are less likely to stay in office longer, whereas county age does not matter much with respect to political survival itself. The type of head of government is much more important in deciding political survival rather than the strength of political survival, although it still accounts for the strength. Party system is not related to political survival, but it has a great influence on the strength of survival. Leaders from single party systems stay in power longer, whereas those from multiparty systems stay in office shorter. There is no relationship between the degree of homogeneity of society (HOMOGEN) and political survival or the strength of survival. Population density (POPDEN) does not matter for political survival or the degree of political survival. In terms Of LITERACY, leaders from societies with high levels - used as an indicator of modernization - are more likely to stay in Office longer. Freedom status as a combination of political and civil rights has a positive influence on political survival but no influence on the degree of durability. Great economic freedom influences whether leaders stay in Office short or not, but does not matter with the degree of their longevity beyond the initial trial period. The less economic freedom, the longer the leader stays. PREDICT 120 Table 7 Success of Prediction in Interaction Model Political Survival (Selection Equation) ACTUAL 0 1 ROW SHORT NOT-SHORT TOTAL 0 122 85 207 SHORT 37.5 15.9 24.0 1 203 451 654 NOT-SHORT 62.5 84.1 76.0 COLUMN 325 536 861 TOTAL 37.7 62.3 100.0 Strength of Political Survival (Substantive Equation) ACTUAL 1 2 3 Row (3 - 6) (7 - 12) (13+) TOTAL 1 298 93 41 432 (3 - 6) 92.3 75.6 45.6 80.6 2 7 8 8 23 PREDICT (7 - 12) 2.2 6.5 8.9 4.3 3 18 22 41 81 (13+) 5.6 17.9 45.6 15.1 COLUMN 323 123 90 536 TOTAL 60.3 22.9 16.8 100.0 121 17. In the case of regional differences, each region does not show any significant relationships with both political survival and the degree of survival. In the substantive equation with the selected sample (563), some variables gain significance and some lose it. While CIVSERV, LIBTECH, OLD, SINGLEP, and MULTIP are shown to be significant, POLALL, FULLFREE, and ECONFREE become insignificant in the substantive equation. In addition, although PREZ is significant at the OI = .10 level, the test level gets weaker (.001 —) .10). Overall, the selection equation obtains 66.6% correctly predicted, and the substantive equation predicts 64.7% correctly. Generally, the two-equation interaction model has a pretty good performance in explaining the relationships between exogenous variables and political survival on the one hand, between the exogenous variables and the strength of political survival on the other hand. Therefore, the results of the interaction model are best for interpreting the main substantive findings of our study. As shown in Table 7, among the correctly predicted cases (66.6%), the interaction model performed better at predicting ’SHORT (0)’ outcomes. The model predicted or correctly classified 84.1% of the ’NOT-SHORT (I)’ leaders and 37.5% Of the SHORT leaders. While the SHORT category does not have a big improvement (2% reduction), NOT-SHORT has 21.8% (62.3% —) 84.1%) of improvement. In the case Of the substantive equation, all three categories show different aspects: category 1 (3 - 6 yrs) had 32% of improvement and category 3 (13 + yrs) does 28.8% of improvement, whereas category 2 (7 - 12 yrs) has rather 16.4% of reduction. All together, the proportion of the correctly predicted cases is 64.7%. The results indicate that the model 122 might be more reasonable to predict ’SHORT’ or ’NOT-SHORT’ than to predict the degree Of political survival. Nonetheless, as shown in Table 8, the interaction model (66.55% correctly predicted and ROE = 11.39) was the best predictor among all the models, even though its ROE is a little bit higher than career backgrounds (ROE = 11.37). Table 8 Goodness-of-F it Of Selection Equations Model % Modal % Correctly ROE Predicted Social Background 61.62% 61.17% -1.17 Career Background 60.17% 64.70% 11.37 Institutional Attn'butes 59.45% 62.62% 7.82 Interaction 62.25% 66.55% 1 1.39 123 B. Analyses of Regional Models As regional dummies, none of them show any significant impact on political survival or the strength of survival in both the reduced models and the interaction model. It is worth breaking the interaction model down region by region in order to see better regional or cultural effect. As seen in Table 9, the results provide different explanations of political survival and the strength of survival. According to the logic of the European mind, every territory should fall under some sovereignty, and all people in the same geographic location should have a common loyalty and the same legal Obligation (Pye, 1985, p.86). If the data is analyzed by looking at different regions of the world, it can be found that different groups of countries show very different patterns (see Table 9). Most of the quantitative explanatory research compasses all or most countries simultaneously. We offer a note of caution about interpreting these results too critically, especially if the researcher has not broken the countries down into types or regional clusters. In Asia, among the personal characteristics, only the educational level is important in explaining whether or not a leader stays in office for a short period. 80, especially, the leader with above college degree is more likely to stay in office for 0 - 2 years. While the leader in a highly homogeneous society and economically free society is less likely to survive for long, the leader in a society with high literacy rate stays in Office longer. In developing countries, such as Asian and Latin American countries, capitalism is equally unsuited to the goals of the revolution since it sows the seeds Of conflict and antagonism. 124 Table 9 Significant Variables in Regional Models Region Selection Equations Substantive Equations Asia URBAN(‘), LITERACY(‘), ECONFREE(‘) FULLFREE (0) HOMOGENP‘) Africa LIBERAu“), CONSERV(”), AGE(”),URBAN(“),LAWPOL(”),CIVSERV(”) ECONFREE(“), M1LITAR(”), LIBTECH”), POLT'WO(‘), POLALw), FORWORK(”), FORBOTH(‘), LIBERAu"), CONSERw"), 0LD(”), PRFZP‘), SINGLEPP‘), POPDENv), LITERACY(”). HOMOGEN”), FULLFREE“); ECONFREEP‘) Middle East AGE("), CONSERV(‘), SINGLEP(”), AGE(‘), COLLEGE(’),URBAN(‘), LAWPOL(‘), MULTTP(“), HOMOGENP‘). M1LlTAR(‘), LIBTECH(‘), FORSTUD(“), OIJX“),SII~1GLEP(‘),POPDEN(‘),PARTFREE(‘), FULLFREE('), LITERACY?) Europe/N. America URBAN(‘), FORBOTH”), PREzv) MULTIP(‘) CONSERV(") Latin America AGE(“), POLTWO(‘), POLALw), PARTFREEv) FORSTUDP‘), FORBOTHP), NCONSTIP) HOMOGENv), ECONFREEv), POPDENv) Oceania NONE NONE ‘ significant at .10 " significant at .05 125 Thus, the higher the economic freedom, the shorter the leader’s duration. They need an appropriate path where all elements participating in the process of production can meet, capable Of supplying society with all the energies enabling it to rebufld its life on the basis of a carefully studied and comprehensive plan. These are very contradictory outcomes that, theoretically, we did not expect. Most of the countries in South and Southeast Asia which gained political independence since 1945, have in common not only political orders but also economic and social orders which have been stripped of their previous leadership. Independence has necessarily meant a change in political and governmental leaders. Unlike its Western counterpart, some factors that are main causes for democracy and modernization may operate as obstacles to economic development. Nonetheless, even those relationships disappear in the model for the strength Of political survival, only FULLFREE is significant at the .10 level. In the African countries, whether a leader’s ideology is liberal or conservative, he should identify his ideology in order to keep his office longer. Also, in a society with a high level of economic freedom, a leader is more likely to survive long. In the substantive equation for testing the relationships between each independent variable and the strength of political survival, most null hypotheses are rejected at the .10 or .05 levels except COLLEGE, FORSTUD, N CONSTI, CENTRE, MULTIP, and PARTFREE, although the directions of the relationship of those variables are different from the expected ones. The outcome indicates that a leader with foreign experience or more political experience has a tendency for staying in office shorter, and that all dummy career backgrounds in the model have a negative relationships with strength of political survival. It is a quite unusual result that has not been found in any other regions. Since achieving 126 independence after World War H, most of the countries have experienced at least one coup d’etat or one civil war, resulting in profound instability. However, the results from the regional models (Africa and the Middle East) confirm the proposition about country age, such that the leaders in old countries are more likely to stay longer in office. The most distinctive finding from the Middle Eastern model is that, for the first time, COLLEGE, turns out to be significant at the .10 level, showing that the more educated (above college education), the longer the duration. Another encouraging result is that a leader in a more homogeneous society stays in office long and longer. As similar as the trends in African leaders, more experience in the political arenas as well as foreign experience are not the supportive qualities for maintaining their power. POPDEN has never been significant in any other models except the substantive equations in Africa and the Middle East. Many of the underdeveloped or developing areas have become the most densely populated regions on earth because of the introduction of modern medical and health-related practices into the societies. Thus, the region becomes a main source of change and social dislocation. It supports the proposition on govemability such that a leader in a sparse area is not easily threatened by political instability and thus is able to acquire efficiency and equity. The size of a country will have a direct bearing upon the kind of power structures that develop there. To be more specific, the smaller the country, the more concentrated its power structure is likely to be. Next, in case of the European and North American countries, FORBOTH and CONSERV have significant impacts on explaining political survival. Western countries are characterized by a high degree of internalized control and a low degree of 127 extemalized control. Therefore, it is not expected that foreign experiences are important for the leaders in this region because most of the countries are already politically and economically developed enough. URBAN and PREZ are shown to be significant, even at the .10 level. Urban born, as an indicator of political socialization, has a negative relationship with political survival, whereas leaders as presidents are more likely to have relatively long duration. As to the strength Of political survival, being different from Afi'ica or the Middle East, almost all exogenous variables except MULTIP do not have any influence on it. A multiparty system has a negative effect on how much longer a leader can stay in office. In this region, like in Asia, AGE is not explained by a life expectancy theory, but rather by a gerontocracy thesis. The seniority system effect indicates that power, prestige, and wisdom accrue to age. Seniority is a major repository of the experience and knowledge of society and is treated with the utmost respect and deference. The most distinctive difference in Europe and North America, HOMOGEN does not explain anything on political survival or its strength. Heterogeneity in society is an inescapable facet Of politics within as well as between countries; internal conflict and instability and external conflict and war Ofien flow from ethnic, linguistic, and religious tensions and processes of mobilization. Nonetheless, in this region, heterogeneity will recede in importance as the modernization process accelerates. The example for this phenomenon that accounts for an increasing share of non-revolutionary violence and non-violent movements are: the Basques in Spain, the Flemings and the Walloons in Belgium, the Bretons in France, the British Celtic in Scotland, North Ireland and Wales, and the French in Quebec. 128 In Latin America, the more political experiences and foreign experiences, the longer the duration. In comparison with other regions, more personal variables have an influence on explaining political survival (SHORT or NOTSHORT). The social and cultural matrix within which Latin American leaders operate at present is such that effective and representative popular democracy is, with really few exceptions, not a feasible alternative (Tannenbaum, 1966, p.144). Thus, the personalist state tends to be governed by a single caudillO-type ruler. The archetypical examples Of personalist states include Cuba’s Batista, Venezuela’s Jimenez, the Dominican Republic’s Trujillo, Paraguay’s Stroessner, and the Somoza’s Nicaragua. For the institutional type, the state is essentially an instrument Of class domination and often the military serve as proxy rulers for the economic leaders (elites). El Salvador and Guatemala fit into this pattern. The autonomous institutional state has a highly developed infrastructure of party or government. In Mexico, the leaders’ ideologies are required Objective environmental factors. Thus, leaders Of institutions should be Open to suggestions regarding efficiency in order to seek ways to enhance institutional viability. The political pendulum swung from Aleman (1946-1952) on the right, Ruiz Cortines (1952-1958) on the right, Luis Echeverria (1970-1976) on the lefi, Lopez Portillo (1976-1982) on the right, de 18 Madrid Hurtado (1982-1988) on the lefi, and so on. Considering the frequent military regimes in this area, it is natural to see that leaders with unforceful entry are more likely to stay in Office for a short period. Thus, shortly after the coups, they are withdrawn by other coup leaders, or they serve as transitional roles and transfer the power to civilian leaders. In addition, POPDEN has a 129 negative relationship with political survival. While some variables shown above at least explain political survival, for the strength Of survival the only one of the freedom index is important, although it (PARTFREE) is significant at the .10 level. Finally, the leaders in Oceania are tested, and none of the variables are shown to be significant in either the selection equation or the substantive equation. The sample size of Oceania is not large enough to use a maximum likelihood estimation and, thus, the analysis on a model in this region is not appropriate. In the typical ML estimation procedure, a large sample size is needed because the desirable properties of the MLE are justified only in large sample situations (Eliason, 1991, p.8)."5 In regional comparison with the selection equations in the interaction model (Table 10), a log likelihood ratio (-2LLR) is used as a criterion for overall significance of the equations, while the percentage of correctly predicted and ROE are available for a test for the goodness-Of-fit Of the model (See Table 8). Except Oceania, these statistics can be applied. Since the substantive equation includes just 27 cases and the selection equation is composed with 41 cases, its analyses are excluded. In Asia, Africa, and Latin America, the selection equations are significant at the .01 level, whereas the selection equation for the Middle East is significant at the .05 level and Europe and North America at the .10 level. Among all regions, the Middle Eastern model represents considerably the best goodness—Of-fit (ROE = 60.46) and 83.3% correctly predicted. On the contrary, the Latin American model shows the lowest goodness-of-fit (ROE = 14.47). However, " It is not specified how large a sample size is enough for MLE. Considering degrees of freedom and a level, a sample size of more than 60 is usually large enough. If d.f. = 60 and a = .05, student-t and the standard unit normal are 2.00 and 1.96 respectively. 130 Table 10 Goodness-Of-Fit of Regional Models Political Survival (Selection Equations) : Region N Modal for % Correctly ROE -2LLR NOT-SHORT (%) Predicted Asia 120 62.50 76.67 37.79 66.04"" Africa 145 67.50 73.79 19.35 65.98"“ Middle East 102 57.84 83.33 60.46 53.44" Europe/N. America 229 56.33 67.69 26.01 4256" Latin America 224 66.07 70.98 14.47 82.56'" " significant at .10 ” significant at .05 "W significant at .01 Strength of Political Survival (Substantive equations) : Region N % Correctly -2LLR Predicted Asia 75 65.33 50.68" Africa 97 53.61 50.10" Middle East 56 83.93 77.99"" Europe/N. America 129 66.67 59.02" Latin America 148 87.16 162.70‘“I " significant at .05 "'" significant at .01 131 among the substantive regional models, the Latin American model (87.16%) and the Middle Eastern model (83.93%) have a better goodness-of-fit than the other models according to the percentage of correctly predicted. However, only one variable (PARTFREE) is significant in the substantive equation of the Latin American mOdel. In the case of the African model, the substantive equation represents several significant exogenous variables, although the model itself shows the lowest percentage of correctly predicted (53.61%). Conclusion The reduced models represented the effect of each variable in three subgroups (social backgrounds, career backgrounds, and institutional attributes). In all three reduced models, the exogenous variables, which had significant effect on political survival, lost their influence on the strength of political survival. Prior to the interactional effect, each reduced model shows a different aspect of goodness of fit. While the social background model and the institutional attributes model improved their goodness-of-fits, the career background model reduced its percentage of correctly predicted. In other words, the career background model explained best for political survival (SHORT or NOT-SHORT), whereas the institutional model accounted for the strength of political survival better than others. As a result, the previous political careers and political activities are very important to the leaders when they are elected as top executives, but maintaining office longer depends on institutional attributes rather than their personal qualities. In the interaction model, we could see the different results in comparison with 132 those in the reduced models. Although the interaction model showed better goodness-of- fit than the reduced models, the relationships of the personal backgrounds and institutional attributes to political survival and the strength of political survival did not appear as much clearly as in the reduced models. Rather, the results presented one interesting finding. The characteristics of political system, i.e. , party system and type of government, are more important for the degree of survival rather than situational condition such as freedom status and economic freedom. The regional models provided some different interpretations the we could not find in the two-equation interaction model. In the African and the Middle Eastern models, similar independent variables have significant influence on both political survival and the strength of political survival due to the cultural similarities and regional closeness. However, the goodness-of—fit measures indicated that the Middle Eastern model predicted leaders’ duration much better than the African Model. It implicated that Middle Eastern countries are more stable than African countries. In the Latin American model, more independent variables had impact on political survival rather than the strength of political survival. Those variables are definitely related to the number of coup d’etat in that area. Meanwhile, in the case of European and North American model, its goodness-of—fit is lower than other regions since most countries in that areas are liberal democratic. A slight increase of prediction in the strength of political survival stemmed from the inclusion of the communist countries. CHAPTER VI Descriptive Analysis of Personal Backgrounds In general, most descriptive statistical analyses employ graphical, tabulated, and numerical techniques for summarizing the information in a collection of data. Sample description is an essential task. We can not really explain or predict something unless we can describe it clearly and accurately. In this study, even though a few of the personal background variables are ordinal, most of them are nominal and the strength of the association is explained by Goodman and Kruskal ’s tau, lamda or Cramer ’s V’, etc. In addition, in the case of the tables with ordinal variables, other statistics such as gamma, Kendall ’s tau, or Somer ’s (1, etc. are available for the relationships. However, the main reason to employ descriptive (analyses here is to compare personal characteristics based on institutional and systematic differences, rather than to examine whether those variables have significant relationships or how strong they are. For this reason, especially in this study, calculating homogeneity scores as well as using graphical comparisons are more helpful to cut through the superficial idiosyncratic nature of the group to uncover the personal characteristics of leaders by typologizing leaders on the theoretically important dimensions such as region, type of head of government, duration of office, and number of entry. Here, the descriptive analyses focus on the elements that contribute to political success and give the details of specific factors. This endeavor yields discussions about what kinds of social backgrounds political leaders have and what the similarities and 133 134 differences are. By using homogeneity scores for the personal background variables such as education, occupation, father’s occupation, age, etc., chief executives can be compared across different regions or different institutions. Many scholars assert that political leaders differ from the rest of the population of the world by their social backgrounds, career backgrounds, and personality and skills. However, it is argued that political leaders themselves have several similarities. Based on group comparisons rather than individual comparisons, we can test the hypothesis that chief executives are everywhere significantly homogeneous. Calculating mean scores of homogeneity in each group of personal backgrounds, it is possible to compare similarities and differences on the basis of different dimensions. There are four-dimension comparisons in homogeneity scores, accompanied by graphical analyses. They include categories of duration, region, type of the head of government, and the number of entry. Also, in each dimension, it is feasible to compare three different personal backgrounds: social backgrounds, career backgrounds, and skills and personality. In fact, even though personality and skills data should not be included in a quantitative empirical method, that is, a previously discussed two- equation model, these variables can be analyzed without considering validity issues in this part for a descriptive perspective or for the readers’ interest. Considering the logic of homogeneity scores, even though the percentage of missing data for certain variables is very high (see note 13), comparisons are possible without losing those variables. 135 A. Comparison by Region Regional comparisons reflect cultural differences. There exists an attitudinal link between leadership and followership that depends on national character and political culture. Followership in different countries is more or less determined by prevailing norms concerning the exercise of political leadership. Culture is defined as the set of properties we attribute to the system by observing the distribution of psychological attributes among the individuals who comprise the system (Singer, 1968, p.141). For example, even though North America is located in a different region from Europe, it is included in the European cultural background. North America was at one time a British colony. Canada has retained its connection with Britain and also certain aspects of the British constitution, while the US. constitution has reflected the political climate in 18th century France. The homogeneity scores of leaders’ age in Asia and Europe presented in Table 11 are higher than other regions since more leaders from those areas became heads of government in their 505 and 605. However, in Afiica and Oceania, younger (less than 50s) leaders had more chances to become heads of government. Gerontopolitics effect is applied better to the former areas because leaders of new countries are somewhat younger than leaders of older countries. Generally speaking, middle age (403 and 50s) is the most popular age for being a head of government in all regions (see Figure 4). Latin American leaders have the highest score on place of birth because a higher proportion of leaders come from urban areas rather than rural areas. More interestingly, while leaders in Asia (57.9%), Africa (58.9%), and Oceania (58.1%), are more likely to come from rural areas, those in EurOpe (57.3%) and Latin America (69.0%) come 136 Table 11 : Homogeneity Scores in Social Backgrounds, Career Backgrounds, and Skills and Personality By Region Homogeneity Scores for: Characteristics Asia Africa Middle East Europe Latin Amer. Oceania Social Background : Age .101 (145) .041 (149) .041 (111) .131 (247) .083 (292) .051 (45) Place of Birth .032 (140) .079 (148) .009 (107) .032 (238) .148 (242) .050 (43) SES .130 (115) .043 ( 80) .020 ( 75) .025 (181) .072 (165) .052 (20) Father’s Occupation .083 (108) .095 ( 76) .105 ( 72) .129 (172) .156 (136) .104 (21) Education .651 (144) .289 (150) .675 (111) .458 (246) .794 (292) .354 (44) Major .123 (138) .066 (130) .094 (104) .214 (215) .120 (279) .203 (35) Mean Score .195 .110 .171 .173 .255 .146 Career Backgrounds : Foreign Experience .147 (144) .397 (150) .131 (111) .030 (246) .044 (293) .225 (44) Military Experience .424 (142) .085 (150) .097 (111) .889 (245) .113 (296) .834 (45) Prison/Exile .094 (142) .117 (150) .108 (111) .255 (245) .266 (296) .683 (45) Political Activity .071 (142) .211 (150) .059 (111) .062 (245) .486 (296) .757 (45) Previous Occupation .082 (144) .225 (150) .148 (111) .083 (245) .144 (294) .122 (45) Experience in Congress .232 (145) .023 (149) .016 (111) .800 (245) .013 (281) .548 (45) Experience in Ministry .470 (145) .394 (149) .511 (111) .349 (243) .226 (288) .531 (43) Party Membership .451 (145) .142 (149) .202 (111) .952 (245) .249 (282) .548 (45) Entry Mode .317 (145) .009 (150) .097 (111) .921 (247) .148 (297) .766 (47) Mean Score .255 .178 .152 .483 .188 .559 Skills and Personality : Oral Skills .159 (128) .413 (133) .291 (81) .129 (201) .213 (199) .231 (33) Organization Skills .023 (128) .153 (133) .031 ( 81) .042 (201) .154 (199) .032 (33) - Language Skills .435 (128) .802 (133) .291 ( 81) .597 (201) .533 (199) 1.000 (33) Party ID .120 (145) .126 (150) .168 (111) .140 (247) .112 (295) .199 (47) Parents’ Death/Separate .795 (128) .699 (133) .688 ( 81) .537 (201) .548 (199) .587 (33) Physical Deformity .395 (128) .514 (133) .404 ( 81) .354 (201) .449 (199) .501 (33) Power Connection .520 (128) .472 (133) .648 ( 81) .942 (202) .640 (199) .886 (33) Mean Score .345 .448 .350 .373 .361 .474 Total Mean Score .267 .246 .212 .373 .252 .435 137 Figure 4 Age Groups by Region [ () is total number of leaders in each region.] Asia (145) Africa (149) lllddle East . H (111) Latin America (292) N. America/Europe (247) Oceania (45) .0-39 40-49 50-59 Deot Figure 5 Educational Level by Region Asia (144) Africa (150) c111) Middle East {“E~* Latin America (292) C 246) N. America/Europe . Oceania (44) High and Below military Bachelor's 7A naster's E] PHD 138 from urban areas. In the case of the leader’s SES, Asian leaders are more homogeneous than leaders in other regions. European leaders are more likely to come from lower classes, whereas Asian and Latin American leaders come from upper classes. Looking at father’s occupations, we can better explain the previous trend. Even though fathers of the leaders in all regions used to be in liberal professions or own business, especially in Asia and Latin America, they worked as party officials, politicians, liberal professions, owners of big farm and ranch, or businessmen, whereas those in Europe and Oceania are more in the area of labor works and farming. In the case of the educational backgrounds (Figure 5), leaders in Asia, the Middle East, and Latin America, are more likely to be highly educated and represent higher homogeneous scores. Furthermore, they possess a higher percentage of military degrees. Meanwhile, in Africa, even though there are higher percentage of high school and below degrees (23.3%), there also exist a higher proportion of military degrees (29.3%). The low homOgeneity scores in Europe (16.3%) and Oceania (18.2%) indicate that there are higher percentage of leaders with high school degree and below. While leaders in all regions had majored in law, political science, or public administration, at college or university, there are higher percentages of such leaders especially in Europe (55.8%) and Oceania (51.4%) (Figure 6). Exceptionally, there are more leaders who went to military schools in the Middle East (33.7%) and the high percentage of leaders with military school degrees are found in Asia (18.8%), Africa (33.1%), and Latin America (31.5%). Career backgrounds can also provide some explanation of cultural differences. Among the regions that have relatively higher homogeneity scores on career variables, 139 Africa has more leaders whose occupations were civil servants, militaries, liberal professions, or owners of big business or ranches. Conversely, leaders in Europe and Oceania are more likely to be in liberal professions or big business rather than in the political arena. The reason for the lowest score for Europe is that the percentage of lawyers and laborers or farmers is much higher than for other regions. Overall, as a unit of occupation, lawyers represent as a stepping-stone for being a top executive. Leaders in Europe (97.7%) and Oceania (93.6%) became top executives through constitutional ways, whereas leaders in Africa (40.1%), the Middle East (35.1%), Latin America (31.0%) and Asia (22.1%) have lower homogeneity scores since higher percentage of leaders acquired power by forceful manners. Simply, it reflects that European countries are politically more stable and developed, and Oceanic countries are politically influenced by the European culture. In explaining foreign experience, professional military experience, prison/exile, and political activity, higher homogeneity scores mean that the percentage of ’Yes’ category is lower. A smaller proportion of European and Latin American leaders had foreign experience than leaders in other regions because it results from whether the countries were colonized before (Figure 7). These European and Latin American countries had been independent, but those in other regions were under colonization by some major powerful countries. The regions that had been under colonization or wars, such as Asia, Africa, and the Middle East, also include a higher percentage of political leaders who had participated in political activities and experienced in prison or exile. Nonetheless, the reason why political leaders in Europe (38.0%) were involved in political activities 140 Figure 6 Majors by Region Africa E 22.3" 5.:»,.,.-,, ”3:. .I.:..w.v». ' - 2 Latin America El; 39.4 (279) 5 O N. America/Europe 17' 55:8 ' 1 15.31 12.015) 3.7 Oceania E 51.4 2’2- (35) Lav/PLS/PA Hed/EIIGR/Itat Sci Erin/Soc SCI/Liter Hilttary E] Business/Econ Figure 7 Foreign, Military, Prison/Exile, and P01. Activity Experiences by Region Asia Africa Hiddle East Latin America N America/Europa Oceania 100 (‘3 I Yoraiqn Experience Professional unitary [:3 prison/Exile [:1 politicai Activity 141 did not result from the independence movements but from the underground activities or resistance movements, such as those against Nazism or Communism. As easily as can be predicted, Europe and Oceania prefer civilian leaders, but there are very high percentages of professional military leaders in Africa (36.0%), the Middle East (35.1%), and Latin America (33.4%). Unlike the previous career experiences, in the case of political experiences, the higher the homogeneity scores, the more ’Yes’ categories. Congressional experience shows a comparatively much higher proportion in Europe (.800) and Oceania (.548) than other regions. However, even though there exist differences between homogeneity scores in ministerial experiences, generally most regions indicate almost the same tendencies (Figure 8). The score for Latin America is a little bit lower than others since there were more professional military men who became heads of government by force. If we consider the inclusion of Defense Minister, Chief of Staff, or Chief of Commander into ministry position, there might be more sudden‘coups in Latin America. Europe (98.8%) and Oceania (86.7%) have a higher percentage of leaders who have party experience due to systematic recruitment of political leaders, that is, parliamentary system, prime minister system, or general secretary system. However, leaders in Africa (68.5%), the Middle East (72.1%), and Latin America (74.8%) do not have as much in the way of party membership as the other regions above. This is because they have been young political systems and, thus, have not established strong party systems. In addition, professional military leaders did not need to be in a party in order to reach to a top executive position. Theoretically, the primary resources for developing political institutions in any 142 Figure 8 Political Experiences by Region Asia Africa Middle East Latin America N America/Europe Oceania Afrlca Hiddle East Latin America N. America/Europe Oceania my , MWMWWWW m w, 32 (Hm: . a. 40 3 - Ora] suns Organization 51: a! I: Llnguaqn Skll ls 143 country is the political skills of its politicians. The political skills needed for developing a viable and self-sustaining political system involve the ideological commitment, the capacity to respond to a new challenge, and the arts of administration, negotiation, and representation. The lower the homogeneity scores for skills and personality (Table 11), the more leaders are included in ’Yes’ categories. However, it is shown that theory does not always match with reality. In Figure 9, relatively more leaders in Europe (32.3%) and Asia (30.5%) have oral skills than those in Africa (18.0%), the Middle East (23.5%), Oceania (27.3%), and Latin America (27.1%). In the case of organizational skills, Afi'ica and Latin American leaders have higher scores (i.e. more leaders without organizational skills) because they have more military leaders. Exceptionally, many leaders in the Middle East have organizational skills (43.2%) and language skills (23.5%). While the leaders in Asia and Africa have relatively more physical deformity and family/power connection, European and Latin American leaders had been more influenced by the fact that their parents died while they were young or that they were separated from their parents early in life. On the contrary, family or power connection is pretty influential in Asia, Africa, and Latin America, but not at all in Europe and the Middle East. Although, in most regions, leaders manifest their party identification, in Africa, party identification is not as important as much as other regions. By and large, regional comparison shows several interesting findings. First of 811, Latin American leaders are the most homogeneous in their social backgrounds, rendered by place of birth (urban), father’s occupation (politicians, landowners) and education (above college including military). Secondly, in the case of career 144 background, Oceanic and European leaders have relatively higher homogeneous scores than those in other regions. It means that countries in both regions have mostly parliamentary systems and, therefore, the peaceful exit mode is more common. While leaders in these regions do not have foreign or military experience, they have experience in political areas, particularly, congress and party. In the aspect of skills and personality, Oceanic and African leaders usually do not have major skills and some sources for establishing their leadership personality. In the case of Africa, a main reason for the higher homogeneous score is that all three skills indicate the lowest percentages compared to other regions. In addition, although the proportions of oral skills and organizational skills are higher, language skills are the main contributor to a higher homogeneous score. In sum, Oceanic leaders are the most homogeneous leaders in their social, career backgrounds, and personality and skills. Since low score represents that the leaders have certain skills, high homogeneous score should be interpreted that there are no skillful leaders. European leaders rank the second in terms of homogeneity which indicates that leaders from parliamentary political systems come from similar social and career backgrounds. 145 B. Comparisons by Duration Based on the highest homogeneous score in age in Table 12, the leaders who stayed very long (21 +) are more likely to become heads of government during their 405. This can be explained by the age effect (see figure 10). If someone starts his leader’s position at younger age, he is more likely to stay in office longer. In the case of birth place, while shorter leaders came from urban area, leaders who came from rural area tended to stay in office longer. In a same fashion, SES, education, and father’s occupation can be explained easily. The longest leaders seem to be from lower classes because their fathers’ occupations were mostly those of laborers or farmers (44.4%). As a result, these leaders could not get higher educations. Among other social background variables, educational degree shows an interesting point in that the longest leaders are likely to have less than high school degrees (36.4%) even though college degrees almost seem to be a requirement. In explaining career backgrounds, all outcomes seem to be easily predicted by common sense. The reason why leaders with the duration of 3 to 10 years got into office through constitutional ways depends on the limited tenure of political requirement. Some countries allow the leaders to stay just one term (4 - 6 yrs), while other countries allow them two sequential terms (8 - 12 years) (see APPENDIX B). Many of the shortest (0 - 2 yrs) leaders acquire power by force or coup d’etat, and such an entry must be regarded as illegitimate (Figure 11). As a result, those leaders just stay for a while to transfer power to another regime or be replaced by another coup. To give a man a lifetime in which to accumulate power is dangerous. A lifetime tenure might even be enough to establish a dynasty - sickness, senility, degeneration, insanity 146 Table 12 : Homogeneity Scores in Social Backgrounds, Career Backgrounds, and Skills and Personality By Duration Homogeneity Scores for: Characteristics 0-2 3-5 6-10 11-20 ' 21+ Social Background : Age .064 (394) .080 (257) .053 (124) .086 (97) .185 (22) Place of Birth .037 (346) .022 (242) .013 (120) .123 (72) .077 (22) SES .043 (206) .044 (176) .012 ( 98) .057 (60) .152 (20) Father’s Occupation .093 (186) .097 (156) .107 ( 93) .064 (56) .220 (18) Education .652 (394) .648 (255) .445 (125) .349 (72) .116 (22) Major .106 (360) .092 (242) .109 (110) .086 (61) .121 (19) Mean Score .190 .178 .130 .131 .143 Career Backgrounds : Foreign Experience .010 (393) .050 (257) .148 (125) .289 (72) .I72 (22) Military Experience .288 (396) .391 (255) .229 (125) .462 (72) .432 (22) Prison/Exile .252 (396) .228 (255) .095 (125) .090 (72) .077 (22) Political Activity .247 (396) .283 (255) .095 (125) .041 (72) .045 (22) Previous Occupation .096 (396) .107 (256) .073 (123) .106 (72) .098 (22) Experience in Congress .103 (384) .285 (256) .166 (125) .163 (72) .330 (22) Experience in Ministry .316 (387) .431 (255) .482 (125) .234 (72) .330 (22) Party Membership .287 (386) .585 (254) .377 (123) .489 (72) .834 (22) Entry Mode .178 (400) .436 (258) .346 (125) .234 (72) .172 (22) Mean Score .197 .310 .223 .234 .258 Skills and Personality : Oral Skills .263 (261) .261 (203) .199 (114) .064 (67) .243 (22) Organization Skills .165 (261) .025 (203) .108 (114) .020 (67) .045 (22) Language Skills .692 (261) .513 (203) .547 (114) .349 (67) .329 (22) Party ID .045 (398) .153 (258) .153 (125) .187 (72) .311 (22) Parents’ Death/Separate .618 (261) .646 (203) .627 (114) .679 (67) .243 (22) Physical Deformity .392 (261) .471 (203) .341 (114) .284 (67) .432 (22) Power Connection .719 (262) .646 (203) .654 (114) .542 (67) .684 (22) Mean Score .388 .379 .373 .302 .327 Total Mean Score .246 .296 .246 .227 .258 147 Figure 10 Age Groups by Duration (394) (257) ( 124) C72) (22) .0-39 ”40-4950-591360. Figure 11 Enter Mode by Duration U — C400) 3 _ (258) 6 - (125) M - 023 29] + 31 8 C22) A; Constitutional [:1 Non—constitutional 148 have tenured good leaders into evil ones; yet an executive appointed for life might not yield power gladly and might have too much power to be dispossessed without violence (Lijphart, 1992, p.60). In reality, even though most countries put a constitutional limitation on tenure of head of government, it is not prone to be effective. Civil servants and professional militaries, or liberal professions and business are the most common professions found among the leaders regardless of duration. However, a higher percentage (27.3%) of laborers and farmers is shown in the longest survivors. Also, leaders who have foreign experiences stayed longer. Since the proportion of non-experiences on professional military, prison/exile, and political activity is higher than the proportion of experiences in each duration category, the lower homogeneity score means more experienced (Figure 12). Consequently, the categories of longer durations (lower homogeneity scores) indicate that there are relatively more leaders who had experiences in prison/exile, and political activities than leaders with shorter durations. In short, graphical presentation shows the leaders with foreign, I prison/exile, and pOlitical activist experiences except military experiences have tendencies to survive longer. . Granting that experiences in congress, ministry, and party are prerequisite for a top executive position, they are needed to be examined in detail. Whether the leaders are short-survivors or long-survivors, remarkably higher proportion of leaders in each duration category had been in political areas prior to their top positions. Nonetheless, there exist some differences to be mentioned. As shown in Figure 13, the leaders who stayed short (less than 2 years) have less experiences in congress (65.9%). In the case of experiences in ministry, the leaders who stayed for medium range of periods (3 - 5 149 Figure 12 Foreign, Military, Prison/Exile, Pol. Activity Experiences by Duration 100 (I) Professional Hilitary I Foreign Experience 1:] Prison/E1119 E] Political Activity Figure 13 Political Experiences by Duration t a fil11'3‘725E‘fl': 100 (‘3 I Party Congress ninistry 150 years, and 6 - 10 years) are more likely to have ministerial experiences. Among the political experience variables, only the party membership indicates a trend of increasing with longevity. The homogeneity scores of the experience in party are usually higher than any other variables. However, the longest leaders (21 +) have the highest homogeneity scores on party membership. 21 out of 22 leaders in that duration have party membership. It is because most leaders in this duration are general secretaries in communist countries. As for skills and personality (Figure 14 and Table 12), with the exception of party ideology, a lower homogeneity score means that there is a higher proportion of ’Yes’ in skills and personality variables. The leaders (38.8%) who stayed for 11 through 20 years tend to have more oral skills than those in other categories. And, in the case of organizational skills and language skills, there are more talented people among the leaders who stayed longer. Distinctively, among the longest survived leaders, there is a higher proportion (27.3%) of leaders whose parents died or separated when the leaders themselves were young. The sources that shaped leaders’ personality have focused on their undernourished relationship with their parents, and an emotional emptiness and thirst for power stemmed from that relationship. For the explanation of party identification, the leaders with conservative party identification are likely to stay longer. In comparison to the leaders in other categories, the leaders with short duration (0 - 2 yrs), are more likely to be non-partisan, independent, or central for party ideology. This is because most of them are military leaders who have never joined parties. Besides social and career backgrounds as well as skills and personality variables, 151 Figure 14 Political Skills by Duration s — «0 (trimaran m (x) I Oral Skills Organization Skills Language Skills Figure 15 Party System by Duration 0 _ 74 S jC4DO) 3 - 81.4 1(2583 5 _ 68.8 (125) 11 (72) 27 3 C22) No Party a Single Party :1 Multiparty 152 some country variables are related with leader’s longevity. Usually, 1/4 or 1/5 of the countries without parties are mostly traditional systems dominated by absolute or near- absolute monarchies, and military regimes set up against parties. However, in this study, they are mostly military regimes, since monarchies were excluded from the sample. Leaders in multiparty systems are likely to stay for shorter durations, while those in single-party systems tend to stay longer (Figure 15). Within single party system, the political career and political roles are very risky because there is ’no place to go’ outside the party. Only through the party can a political career be achieved, and dismissal from the party is oblivion, purgatory, or worse. High political risk and high rewards attract the ambitious and compel their compliance. The functions of nominating and electing candidates for political office are attributed exclusively to political parties. The degree of competition and monopoly in party systems affects political turnover and the circulation of leadership. Especially, most countries with single-party systems are the Communist regimes and some Third World countries (i.e. Ivory Coast, Kenya, Guinea, Zambia, Tanzania, Syria, Iraq, Egypt, etc). Therefore, in socialist economic system, leaders tend to stay longer. Even though capitalist economic systems are popular in other categories of duration, the shortest duration is likely to have the highest percentage of capitalist economic system. As a result, if a society has more freedom in politics or economy, leaders in that society tend to stay shorter. It is interesting to find an extraordinary case such that the shortest leaders are found in high level of political right index (40%) as well as low level (36.8%). In comparison of homogeneity scores on personal variables by duration, the 153 shortest leaders (0 - 2 years) represent the highest Similarity on social backgrounds, whereas leaders in 3-5 years are relatively similar in career backgrounds. However, except for party ideology, the longer-survived leaders have lower homogeneity scores in skills and personality because they possess more skills and personality segments than others. Total mean scores finally indicate there is not much difference between the degrees of similarity of the leaders. 154 C. Comparisons by Type of Head of Government Among the 997 top executives since 1945, there are only 12 females and 60% of them (7 leaders) are prime ministers and the others (5 leaders) are presidents. ‘7 None of the female leaders were ever general secretaries. Even though they were elected by national assembly or national election, some of them had filled the place of their late husbands or some were offsprings of well-known former prime ministers. However, more than one-half of them had been elected through a competition with male candidates. Surprisingly, it is rare to find female head of governments in advanced liberal democracies, but rather they are mostly from developing or underdeveloped countries. Exceptionally, until now, there are no female leaders found in African countries. According to the homogeneity scores in Table 13, especially with respect to the social background variables, presidents and prime ministers have similar characteristics, but general secretaries require different explanations. General secretaries are more likely to be older when they arrive at the top (Figure 16). Even though the scores of birth place are same for all types of leaders, general secretaries (56.3%) are from rural areas and others (55.2% for Presidents and 52.2% for prime ministers) from urban areas. While most presidents (40.4%) and prime ministers (44.7%) came from upper ’7 Female top executives are Isabella Peron (1974 - 1976) in Argentina, Lidia Guelier Tejada (1979) in Bolivia as an interim leader, mary Eugenia Charles (1980 - ) in Dominica, Indira Ghandi (1967 - 1977, 1980 - 1984) in India, Golda Meir (1969 - 1974) in Israel, Agatha Barbara (1982 - 1989) in Malta, Violeta Chamorro (1990 - ) in Nicaragua, Gro Harlem Bnmdtland (1981, 1986 - 1989) in Norway, Benezir Bhutto (1988 - 1991) in Pakistan, Corazon Aquino (1987 - 1992) in Philippines, Sirimaro Bandarike (1960 - 1965, 1970 - 1977) in Sri Lanka, and Margaret Thatcher (1979 - 1990) in England. 155 classes, general secretaries (61.9%) had lower class backgrounds since their fathers’ occupations were mostly laborers or farmers (65.8%). They could not get as much support for education by their fathers as other types of leaders. Consequently, high school degrees are more common among general secretaries (35.4%), whereas the others have more college degrees. There is a high percentage of militarily educated presidents (33.1%). Because military leaders are included in presidents, there are more nonconstitutional exits than other types. Most leaders, regardless of types of leadership, study political science, law, or public administration. However, interestingly, medicine or engineering (34.3%) are found just as much as aforementioned among general secretaries. Among the different occupations previously mentioned, liberal professions or business owners are commonly found in all types of head of government. Actually, civil Figure 16 Age Groups by Type of Head of Government President 20-8 (562) Prime llinister 29 B (379) General Secretary 31 3 (48) We-asII4o-4950-59D50+ 156 Table 13 : Homogeneity Scores in Social Backgrounds, Career Backgrounds, and Skills and Personality By Type of Government and Number of Entry Homogeneity Scores for: Characteristics President Prime General Once 2 + Minister Secretary Social Background : Age .038 (562) .077 (379) .131 (48) - .045 (861) .165 (128) Place of Birth .013 (506) .005 (364) .036 (48) .004 (793) .036 (125) SES .014 (340) .041 (254) .210 (42) .010 (542) .090 ( 94) Father’s Occupation .093 (303) .080 (244) .375 (38) .082 (499) .096 ( 86) Education .630 (562) .548 (377) .104 (48) .561 (860) .587 (127) Major .094 (524) .185 (342) .124 (35) .085 (786) .150 (115) Mean Score .166 .169 .156 .147 .199 Career Backgrounds : Foreign Experience .085 (563) .020 (377) .082 (48) .050 (860) .086 (128) Military Experience .077 (563) .810 (378) .771 (48) .258 (861) .613 (128) Prison/Exile .153 (563) .347 (378) .023 (48) .222 (861) .078 (128) Political Activity .258 (563) .180 (378) .063 (48) .209 (861) .105 (128) Previous Occupation .140 (563) .089 (378) .102 (48) .134 (861) .108 (128) Experience in Congress .004 (553) .689 (376) .695 (47) .111 (849) .532 (127) Experience in Ministry .351 (557) .487 (376) .024 (46) .315 (851) .663 (128) Party Membership .173 (553) .818 (376) .844 (48) .344 (850) .821 (127) Entry Mode .068 (568) .755 (381) .572 (48) .225 (869) .638 (128) Mean Score .145 .466 .354 .207 .404 Skills and Personality : Oral Skills .263 (421) .149 (309) .235 (45) .241 (670) .075 (105) Organization Skills .138 (421) .021 (309) .027 (45) .063 (670) .075 (105) Language Skills .499 (421) .630 (309) .683 (45) .610 (670) .574 (105) Party ID .101 (566) .140 (381) .947 (48) .100 (867) .118 (128) Parents’ Death/Separate .634 (421) .620 (309) .548 (45) .641 (670) .515 (105) Physical Deformity .479 (421) .361 (309) .324 (45) .444 (670) .262 (105). Power Connection .604 (421) .737 (310) .834 (45) .670 (671) .659 (105) Mean Score .375 .372 .538 .384 .319 Total Mean Score .216 .364 .361 .243 .326 157 servants or military professions (42.3%) are the most popular for the presidents, whereas lawyers (23.3%) are second most for the prime ministers and laborers or farmers (27.1%) for the general secretaries. Regardless of the types of leaders, there are more leaders with foreign experience than those with nonexperience. Experience in prison/exile (52.1%) seems to be common to the general secretaries and it results from frequent political activities (60.4%). In comparison of political experience, working in congress seems to be very important to the leaders who want to be prime ministers or general secretaries. Meanwhile, although being a congressman seems to be a springboard to political success, working as a Minister is more important in presidential systems and prime Figure 17 Political Skills by Type of Head of Government Pre51dent V Prime Minister General Secretary I Oral sxiiis Organization sniis Language Skills 158 minister systems. Of course, party membership is very important in all types of leadership, but in a presidential system its significance is reduced because military coup leaders easily become top executives. Comparisons of skills and personality do not provide any significant differences of homogeneity scores. Nevertheless, more prime ministers (30.0%) have oral skills, general secretaries (53.3%) have organizational skills, and presidents (14.3%) have rather language skills (Figure 17). In terms of the personality variables, general secretaries have more than other types, especially physical deformity and separation or death of parents. However, presidents had more power/family connection than other types. Party identification does not explain much at all since general secretaries are from the systems mainly controlled by communist parties. Overall comparisons indicate that overall social backgrounds do not provide any serious impacts on leaders’ similarities, that prime ministers and general secretaries are more similar in their career backgrounds, and that general secretaries have relatively higher homogeneous scores on skills and personality than other types of heads. In general, presidents are more heterogeneous than prime ministers or general secretaries. With respect to the electoral procedure of top executives, people may choose more diverse leaders by direct popular elections or national assemblies, whereas indirect electoral systems generally prefer top executives with similar backgrounds. 159 D. Comparisons by Number of Entry In this part, the homogeneity scores of Table 13 provide the comparisons between the leaders who became heads of government only once and those who did so more than twice. Number of entry does not give as much in terms of the difference as other factors that are compared previously. However, it is necessary to check out some variables that contribute some influence on their similarities. In case of the social background variables, there does not exist much difference between the two groups of leaders. The leaders who became top executives more than twice have higher scores on age, since they started during their 408 for the first time and thus for subsequent terms their ages are getting older than the first time. There are more leaders from upper class (50.5%) among the leaders who have been in office more than twice. Figure 18 Foreign, Mil., Prison/Exile, and P01. Act. Exp. by Number of Entry Once more Than Twice 0 20 40 60 90 (*3 '1r Pr012531ona1 Hilitary I Foreign Experience Prison/Exile Political Activity 160 Figure 19 Political Experiences by Number of Entry Once \ more Than Twice 874 5 g l r l r l r l r U 20 41] 60 80 100 (“J I Party Congress flinistry Figure 20 Personality by Number of Entry Once More Than Twice 3O (90 I PhySical Delorlanca Parents' Death/Separation Power Connection 161 On the contrary, it is easy to find significant differences with career backgrounds. The reason why the leaders who have been in office more than twice have higher scores on constitutional exit mode is that previously experienced leaders might have gotten out of office in peaceful ways and thus got into office for the second time or more via constitutional ways. Quite a few of one-term leaders have gotten into office through coups or forceful ways. It purports other trends: the scores on military experience is low for the leaders who have been in office once, since many of them got there by forceful ways. In the opposite to military experience, prison/exile experience or political activity seems to be a big advantage to be in office again (Figure 18). Also, leaders with more than two terms have more experience in congress, ministries, and parties (Figure 19). As a result, to be a head of government more than twice is related to political experiences or political activities rather than military experiences. While the leaders who became top executives more than twice have more oral skills than the leaders who did once, the other skills (organizational skills and language skills) do not show much difference. However, the leaders with more than twice have a relatively higher proportion of all three personality characteristics, i.e., parents’ death or separation, physical deformity, and power/family connection (Figure 20). Here again, the similarities in career as well as social backgrounds are easily found among the leaders who became top executives more than twice. Nonetheless, even though the leaders who were in office only once possess higher similarities, those similarities are toward the direction of non-possession of skills and personality. In other words, as we assumed, the leaders with more than two terms comparatively have 162 more skills and the causes of personality formation. Above all, the homogeneity scores of the leaders based on number of entry tell us that leaders with more than two terms are more similar to each other than one-term leaders. CHAPTER VII CONCLUSION The decline of authoritarian rule in Southern Europe, Latin America, and other regions in the 19708 and 1980s, as well as the collapse of communism in Eastern Europe and Soviet Union in the beginning of 1990s, may represent the most significant and encouraging historical trends of the turbulent and often tragic twentieth century. Authoritarianism is now on the wane and democracy on the rise across the globe in spite of widespread mid-century pessimism about the prospects for democratic governance (Rustow, 1990). As the expectation for the rise of civilian and constitutional rule grows, leadership change may be an important prospect in political science. As mentioned by Huntington (1991, p.315), the two key factors affecting the future stability and expansion of democracy are economic development and political leadership. Democracy contributes to stability by providing regular opportunities for changing political leaders and changing public policies. An institutional or tactical analysis of political development is usually related to a crucial problem for leaders - how to survive in power. As long as politics is defined as a process that is deeply and intricately interwoven between governing and power struggle, political leadership may be explained rationally based on the stability and security of the system and irrationally on the basis of motivation for getting into top positions in politics. Thus, the chief executive is the lead actor in the political drama of contemporary society, since the position refers to the political head of government rather than to the ceremonial chief 163 164 of state. According to Confucius’ thought and the pre-Christian philosopher’s perspectives, "If the ruler is virtuous, the people will also be virtuous." Even though classical literature has provided several qualities and conditions for ideal leaders, the image of political leaders has changed over the years. The qualities of leaders definitely are no longer important for their successful survival. As long as the selection procedures are democratic, people choose their leaders by participating in elections. In addition, political culture is better conceived not purely as the legacy of the communal part but as a geological structure with sedimentary deposits from many historical ages and events (Diamond, 1993, p.412). In each new historical period, new value orientations have partially displaced but not completely erased preexisting ones. As one of the dimensions on political performance, durability as a concept of stability should be considered. Especially in political leadership, that is, a position of a head of government, its stability definitely relates to its longevity. If political stability is defined as stability and continuity of basic political institutions and processes themselves, institutional longevity which measures the long-term stability of political structures should be based on the leaders’ longevity. The length and terms of tenure must be sufficient to permit the holders to perform their offices, but not so long as to permit tenure to become entrenchment in office. They must be secure enough to permit incumbents to govern, but not so secure as to encourage complacency or corruption in Office. The study of political stability does not require justification in terms of the importance of the phenomena related to it. Rather it requires some establishment of 165 boundaries within which the process of interest can be studied. Sometimes it will be shown that the most stable systems, whether domestic or international, are at the same time the most predictable ones in a very simple sense - the ability based on performance to predict the performance of that system at the same future time. Political Success, actually, depends on performances in office as well as "rally-around-the-flag effects" from international crises. Being the right person is almost as important as "being in the right place at the right time" (Sirnonton, 1984, p.165). However, since failures of the system are fault of incompetent power-holder, the situation can be greatly improved by changing the incumbent authorities. The resulting stability in the administrative structure makes it possible to have the everyday lives of ordinary citizens to remain largely unaffected even by the changes of national leaders. Therefore, the power of the people to control government is the negative power to remove a government from office and replace it. As Simon mentioned (1965), "Political leadership is like a bus driver whose passengers will leave him unless he takes them in the direction in which they wish to go, they leave him only minor discretion as to the road to be followed." As a result, nondemocratic structure may frequently be relatively stable. In case of the democratic structure, it is definitely true that being a great power is no longer fun (Schoenbaurn, 1973). The effort to base legitimacy on performance sometimes gives rise to what can be termed the performance dilemma. Indeed, predictions on duration in office can be different from legal duration even where leaders are elected for a fixed term, especially in constitutional presidencies. For example, in many Latin American countries, presidents often have to resign or are dismissed by coups before the end of their legal 166 term. In addition, it is possible to see more changes of top executives in countries whose political institutions are less stable. Meanwhile, the length of a particular presidency may depend partly on personal influence, namely on the president’s ability to get himself renominated and reelected. No American president in nearly half a century, not even Eisenhower, managed to sustain such high level of public trust. Reagan was the first president since Eisenhower to finish eight full years in office and the first one since Andrew Jackson to leave office safe in the knowledge that his vice president had been elected to succeed him (Etheredge, 1993, p.149). Sometimes, the transfer of political power never resulted from a set of accepted, well-defined, institutionalized procedures. For example, in China prior to 1949, the individuals in collective leadership - and hence the serious contenders for Mao’s mantle of power - had to possess some particular qualifications. The main answers for this study in empirical aspects would be focused on two possibilities: (1) Is it possible to employ personal characteristics as well as situational characteristics to construct a composite profile of individuals who, in a given society, are likely to be successful leaders (SHORT or NOT-SHORT) ?; (2) Is it possible to utilize them to arrive at a composite profile of individuals who turn to be the different level of successful leaders (Who are more successful? or How longer do leaders stay? ) ? In addition, through descriptive analyses, similarities and differences on personal characteristics of the leaders, including skills and personalities, have been discussed on the basis of region, duration, type of head of government, and number of entry. In this study, 17 hypotheses have been tested using a two-equation model in an effort to see the relationships between personal backgrounds and institutional 167 characteristics and political survival and its strength as political success. Three reduced models - social backgrOund model, career background model, and institutional model - were examined to see the effect of independent variables in each model and to compare which model explains and predicts better for political survival. An interaction model, which includes all explanatory variables from all three reduced models, has been tested for finding which makes leaders stay in office for a short period or not (selection equation) and for how long (substantive equation). Even though 17 hypotheses are mainly tested, actually each model has more tests since several dummies are included because most independent variables are nominal. All models have evaluated what elements are appropriate for explaining and predicting duration of office as the indicators for political survival of heads of government across the countries since 1945 until 1992. Predictability is confined to the large aggregates of data over long time periods. Whereas all selection equations contain 984 leaders after data manipulation, only 581 leaders are included in all. substantive equations after the selection procedure. In addition, regional models have been tested to see cultural effects. In each reduced model, some independent variables proved statistically significant or possibly significant only in the selection equation, that is political survival. However, none of them proved significant in the substantive equation for the strength of political survival. Meanwhile, in the interaction model, more independent variables turned out to be significant in the substantive equation than in the selection equation. All individual effects on political survival in each reduced model are almost similar to those in the interaction model. So, in this conclusion, the discussion will be 168 focus on the individual effects from interaction model. One of the most interesting findings concern the vanishing effect of significant independent variables when explaining the strength of political survival in all three reduced models. The reason why some independent variables explain only political survival and not the strength of political survival is due to honeymoon effects that all political leaders face. New leaders do plan to affect public policy during their honeymoons because they have the desire and the capacity to do so during their terms. Therefore, after a certain short period (0 - 2 years), known as the honeymoon period, social and career backgrounds of the leaders definitely tend to be less important as much as in election times or the selection procedures. Those personal backgrounds seemed to be crucial for the people to elect or select the leaders on the basis of the leaders’ image established by their personal characteristics, not based on their political performance, that is, institutional characteristics. In general, in explaining political survival (selection equation) itself, at least one of the dummy ,variables for each of the independent variables on social and career backgrounds, except entry mode (NONCONSTI) proved statistically significant for the hypothesis testing. Conversely, most institutional characteristics, such as country age (OLD), party system (SINGLEP and MULTIP), homogeneity index (HOMOGEN), population density (POPDEN) and region did not prove significant at all. Those variables which were found to explain best why leaders stay short or not, are mostly personal backgrounds of the leaders before entering their top executive office. All three social backgrounds, such as age, education, and birth place were statistically significant, although directions of the relationships were opposite to the 169 expected for college degree and urban born. As one would expect, at least one of the dummies of career backgrounds, i.e., political experience (POLALL), foreign experience (FORSTUD and FORBOTH), and political ideology (CONSERV) were proven to be significant, but previous occupation (LAWPOL) had a negative relationship with political survival. Those who had been lawyers and politicians before entering into a top executive position are probably more vulnerable to withdrawal by sudden military coups. Moreover, those professions are more favorable in liberal democracies with prime minister systems in which leadership transfers are very frequent. Type of government (PREZ) as an indicator of institutional difference and literacy rate (LITERACY), freedom status (FULLFREE), and economic freedom (ECONFREE) as the indicators of modernization proved statistically significant or possibly significant. Surprisingly, economic freedom is yet negatively related to political survival. Perhaps, as an indicator of modernization, it tells instead that leaders in the societies with low economic freedom are more likely to stay in office longer since those societies are not economically stable, and, thus, leaders tend to remain in power until they boost the economy up to a certain stage that makes the polity stable both economically and politically. Nonetheless, in comparison with other two reduced models (selection equations), the career background model shows the best goodness-of-fit. In other words, in order to explain and predict whether leaders stay in office for a short period (0 - 2 Yrs.) or not, the previous experiences in foreign countries and political arenas as well as political ideology, that is, orientations toward politics, are the most important factors. Even though each three reduced model proved Significant for the test of the whole 170 model using -2LLR in both selection model and substantive model, the hypotheses testing on each independent variable are not available in the substantive equation of each reduced model. Consequently, in order to find the relationships with a number of the indicators above and the strength of political survival (substantive equation), the results from the interaction model are inspected. While social background variables did not show any difference from the selection equation, some in career backgrounds and some in institutional attributes provide somewhat different outcomes. When comparing the findings of the selection equation with those from the substantive equation, the following structure of results could be observed. First of all, all dummies concerning political experience in career backgrounds did not prove statistically significant at all. To the leaders who already have spent two more years in office, political experience is irrelevant to the prediction of the strength of political survival. Instead, their political performance during their tenure is probably much more vital. Second, country age and party systems became important in explaining the strength of political survival. The findings indicate that the leaders in young countries and in single party systems are more likely to maintain power longer. By and large, the young countries have not been in a firm base of political stability since their independence from colonization, and usually a founder of the national party or a first leader of the country would have maintained his office until the new country was settled down as a stable polity.I 2' For examples, they are Pindling in Bahamas (1967 - ), Kharna in Botswana (1966 - 1980), Ahidjo in Cameroon (1960 - 1982), Pereira in Cape Verde (1975 - ), Gouled Aptidon in Djibouti (1977 - ), Jawara in Gambia (1965 - ), Sekou Toure in Guinea (1958 - 1984), Houphouet-Boigny in Ivory Coast 171 Third, freedom status and economic freedom indicating situational differences have lost their significance and thus could not predict the strength of political survival any more. The leaders who already have stayed in office over 2 years might be exempted from the threat of political and economic instability. Rather, more institutional factors, as mentioned earlier, such as country age, party systems, and type of head of government, are very supportive in predicting the strength of political survival. Above all, the interaction model showed the best goodness-of-fit among the models that have been discussed in both the selection equation and the substantive equation. Additionally, it is more possible to test the relationships between independent variables and political survival and the strength of political survival, which the substantive equation in each reduced model by itself could not find. However, based on the success table (Table 7) as well as the percentage of correctly predicted, the model itself might be more desirable to predict political survival than to predict the strength of political survival. Although regional dummies have never been significant in the models, dividing the interaction model by region has shown different findings. African and Latin American models include mainly more personal variables which are significant when explaining political survival, whereas for the strength of political survival Middle Eastern and African models showed several significant indicators not only for personal background but also for institutional attributes. Overall, while the Middle Eastern (1960 - ), Kenyatta in Kenya (1964 - 1978), Banda in Malawi (1964 - ), Senghor in Senegal (1960 - 1981), Pinto da Costa in Sao Tome and Principe (1975 - ), Nyerere in Tanzania (1961 - 1985), Lini in Vanuatu (1980 - ), Kaunda in Zambia (1964 - ), etc. 172 model has the best goodness-of-fit in explaining political survival itself, the Latin American and Middle Eastern models are proven to be the best in accounting for the strength of political survival. The question, whether the data from diverse cultures and time periods are functional, should be overcome by minimizing as much as possible the introduction of ethnocentric or otherwise biased materials. However, justification of gathering social information for the comparative study of political leadership seem to withstand most criticisms on empirical inefficiency. In contrast to the general elite studies, it is much easier and more possible to collect reliable social background and career paths of the leaders as heads of government since they are much better known and publicized than other elites groups. The only one problem is that it is very difficult to collect and operationalize psychological information. While it is possible to find leaders’ personal histories, past achievements, and basic political philosophies, their skills or personalities, such as hobbies, habits, and weak points, do not receive much attention, and, therefore, it is not easy to find some crucial psychological factors. Hence, it is not easy to identify the individual traits that contribute to leader’s success. Many scholars believe that the study of political leadership as we find it in the context of contemporary social psychology is no longer a study of the mighty, of the personalities and behaviors of the outstanding figures of modern society, but of the many minor heads, bosses, and superiors of everyday, mainly institutional, life. If ’fitness’ for a certain position becomes less evolutionary and more social, reputation or status - family and class background, education, profession, money, etc. - are substitutes for real competitive proofs. By ’worth’ is meant that set of qualities and conditions that 173 society values in assigning social class rank; it is what the electorate admires. For example, those that in the past have rated highest are; in China, scholarly learning and prowess at killing games; in India, Brahman birth; in Europe, royal birth (Girvin, 1989). However, instead of parents’ worth, personal worth, that is recognized socially as personal attributes, is included in the new formula for worth. Some background characteristics have more relevance than others for political success within same political systems. A priori use of background characteristics as explanatory variables has different effects for different types of heads of government in different regions of the world. However, gross similarities between the social backgrounds or career backgrounds of heads of government can not be used as proof of political success or failure and the degree of their success. Significance of those backgrounds for political success is greater in developing societies than in societies with more stable political institutions. Therefore, the impact of social and career backgrounds on political success remains plausible, but ambiguous and unsubstantiated. It would seem that long leadership will tend to prevail in countries where the extent of social and economic change is low. Elsewhere, the occurrence of long leadership would hinge on the presence of special conditions countering the propensity of leaders to be rapidly weakened by social change. Even though biographies often endeavor to give descriptive accounts of the personality characteristics of the political leaders, it is premature to begin discussing the impact of personality as we did not know which ’traits’ were relevant to political success. Like any quantitative researches, in this study, we can find that measures of duration of office are limited to the year unit and typically insensitive to some validity 174 problems. By nature, the sample, here, is a censored sample in which some observations on the dependent variable corresponding to known sets of independent variables are not observable. Using the duration of office as the dependent variable poses new problems. First, the value of the dependent variable is unknown or censored for the leaders who ere not out of office during the observed period. The second problem is how to include explanatory variables that change in value over the observation period. There is no satisfactory way of incorporating time-varying explanatory variables in a multiple regression predicting time of an event. As a solution for the former problem, in order to reduce the problem of missing data on duration office resulted from censoring, the leaders who are still in office during the observed period need to be given elaborate consideration. They make up 11.5 % (115 cases) of the total leaders examined (997 cases) and excluding them from the analysis is not a reasonable solution. Thus, considering the theoretical aspects, only the short durations (0 - 2 yrs) during the observed period are excluded. It is not a perfect solution for missing data, but at least it prevents from losing many available information. Most situational explanatory variables incur the second problem stated above since their value are changing over time. If continuous variables themselves, such as freedom status, economic freedom, literacy, population density, age of country, etc., are considered as annual data, the measurements of the year when the leader became a head of government are used. However, the unavailable data are replaced with the values of the closest year even though they are not accurate. However, in case of the stationary variable, i.e., homogeneity index, it is reasonable to use given values of a 175 certain year when the leader started his office as a head of government since its change over the years is not seriously enormous. _ Although we investigate as many potential causes of successful political leadership as the available data allowed, some important variables - SES, father’s occupation, major in school, or skills and personalities - have undoubtedly been omitted from the causal system. If something related to them could be found, it might be general enough across time and space to lend itself to predictive testing when applied to contemporary and future leaders, men for whom extensive biographical data would not be available, but for at least some of whom sufficient articulated data might be. Thus, these data are just analyzed in a descriptive way. If the results of the estimation provide justification or corroboration for theoretical perspectives on political survival, then it could be argued that this model has led to some progress in the field. Not only disproof, invalidation, lack of progress, but also satiation due to overresearching an area are the most frequent motives for the discontinuous nature of historical change in the sciences. Many people assert that the greatest weakness of research in this field has not been a lack of facts but the disparity between theory and empirical research. Despite masses of accumulated data, it is necessary to find rather few general relationships between demographic, career background, and situational factors and political survival as political success. Andreas Pickel (1989, p.90) asserts, "We should try to improve and expand our knowledge by criticizing rather than by justifying our theories, by searching for refutations rather than confirmations." Even though some stand up more successfully to criticism than others, and this is why they can be considered closer to the truth than others, constructive 176 search for refutation still forces us to develop new and better theories. The study of political survival as political success based on leader’s duration in office is important in at least a couple of reasons. First, individual leaders have different qualities associated with being top executives which people expect, despite social backgrounds or career backgrounds. Second, polities differ in the economic and political output of the government, such as economic freedom, political system, freedom index, party system, type of head of government, and so on. Therefore, as Rousseau mentioned, it is true that the strongest is never strong enough to always be the master unless he transforms strength into right and obedience into duty. Finally, there is some motivation that individual leaders need to stay longer as top executives. However, these psychological aspects can not be generalized by some collected biographical information because of the lack of validity and reliability of the sources. Personal attributes of leaders have a large effect. They relate to deeper elements of the personality or to events that occurred in childhood. Leaders have to be able to grasp what is important and what is trivial, to weigh alternatives, to foresee possible outcomes. Decision-making a matter of will power and courage, the leader has to have the emotional ability to stop the debate in his mind and take a particular side. RECOMMENDATION If it is possible to find other information on certain background variables, such as birth order, sibling combination, religion, and ethnicity, etc., it will provide an even more interesting explanation on political success. According to Stewart (1977), the relationship between birth order and political Zeitgeist is explained as follows: F irst- 177 born may have superior odds of success in times of crisis, with the proviso that middle children be more disposed toward political leadership (They are more likely to lead in periods of calm.) and later-born children toward revolution. These tendencies may arise from childhood patterns of sibling relationship (Galton, 1874: Rejai and Phillips, 1983). As Weber repeatedly emphasized, it is not necessarily what the leader is but how he is perceived by his followers that is decisive for the validity of charisma (Willner, 1968, p.4). In so far as charisma can be seen as a quality of an individual, it lies in his capacity to project successfully an image of himself as an extraordinary leader. In other words, charisma is a certain quality of an individual personality. In biographies or the documents about the political leaders, it may not be difficult to find the description indicating charismatic personality - acuteness, eye for detail, ideological ’founding father’ or ’initially’ charismatic leader, discriminatory powers of the observer and recorder, nonverbal behavior. With this subject, the research should be narrowed down to the certain limited target population. APPENDICES APPENDIX A Data Collections and Data Codebook A. Data Sources The most important data sources for collecting information on the leaders as heads of government in each country and their duration of office are Heads of State and Government (1985), Elections since 1945: A Worldwide Reference Compendium (1989), World Atlas of Elections 1986 (1987), The International Almanac of Electoral History (1991), etc. The main sources of social background variables are Current Biography, New York Times Biographical Edition that accumulates the articles of Man of the News, Keesing '3 Contemporary Archives, Current World Leaders (1960 - ), Almanac of Current World Leaders, Encyclopedia of World Biography, Who ’s Who in the World, International Who 's Who, The Annual Obituaries (1980 - ), The Britannica Yearbook, Who 's Who in Modern World: 1860 - 1980, Historical Dictionary series of each country, and several biographies from some specific regions or countries, such as Biographical Dictionary of Latin American And Caribbean Political Leaders, Dictionary of Irish Biography, Encyclopedia of Latin America, Who ’s Who in Africa, Makers ofModern Africa, Encyclopedia of Asian History, Who ’ Who in Australasia and Far East, etc. The sources for institutional data are World Quality of Life Indicators, World Development Report, Britannica World Data, Political Parties of the World, and World Handbook of Political and Social Indicators III: 1948 - 1982, World Urbanization: 178 I950 - 1970, Freedom in the World, 1974 - 1990, The New Book of World Rankings, and etc. 179 180 B. Operationalization and Measurement Dependent Variable Duration of Office (DURATION or DURACAT) : For a two-equation model, duration of office as a continuous variable is divided into 4 categories (DURACAT). And, for the descriptive analysis, it is categorized into 5 values (DURATION). DURATION: DURACAT: O=O-2 O=0-2 l=3-6 l=3-5 2=7-12 2=6-10 3=13+ 3=11~20 4=21+ Indemndent Variables (a) Social Backgrounds of Individual Leaders Age (when the person became a leader)(AGE or AGECAT) : Age is used as a continuous variable in the two-equation model, whereas it is categorized for the descriptive analysis. O=Under40 l=40-49 2=50-59 3=60and0ver Place of Birth (BPLACE): O = Rural + Foreign Country 1 = Urban (Cosmopolitan areas) + Capitol Father’s SES (SES): 0 = Low 1 = Middle 2 = Upper 181 Degree of Education (DEGREE): It is operationalized in two different ways: DEGREE (l) for the descriptive analysis and DEGREE (2) for the two- equation model. DEGREE (l) DEGREE (2) 0 = Below High School 0 = Below High School 1 = Coll/Univ. (BA, BS, LLB) 1 = Above College 2 = Master’s (MA, MS) 3 = Doctorate (LLD, MD, PhD) 4 = Military Major of Education (MAJOR): O = Law/PLS/Diplomacy/Public Administration 1 = Medicine/Pharmacy/Engineering/Nattual Science/Agriculture 2 = Journalism/Language/Education/Social Science/Theology 3 = Business/Accounting/Finance/Economics 4 = Military Father’s Occupation (FATHOCCU): Since it is very difficult to collect the information of father’s occupation, ’Not Available’ is included as one of the categories of the variable. 0 = Lawyer 1 = Civil Servant/Military 2 = Party official/Politician/Political Activist/Union Activist 3 = Journalist/Teacher/Professor/Liberal Profession/ Business/Own Farms fTechnical/White Collar/Medical Doctor/ Engineer/Accountant 4 = Manual Laborer/ Small Wage Earner/Farmer/Agriculture 5 = Not Available (b) Career Backgrounds Party Membership (PARTEXP): If a leader had joined in a party, it is coded as 1. 0=No 1=Yes 182 Experience of Ministerial Position or a Chief of Staff (MINIEXP): If someone has been in office as a minister of a certain department or in almost the same level of a powerful position such as a Chief of Staff in military or a Commander of army, it is coded as l. I 0=No 1=Yes Experience in Congress (CONGEXP): Regardless of the differences between lower, and upper house or senators and congressmen, if someone has been elected for Congress, it is coded as 1. 0=No 1=Yes Political Experience (POLEXP): 0 = None 1 = Party or Congress or Ministry Only 2 = Party + Congress/Party + Ministry/Ministry + Congress 3 = Party + Congress + Ministry Career before getting into Politics (CAREER): CAREER (1) for the two-equation model 0 = Lawyer 1 = Civil Servant/Military 2 = Party Official/Politician/Political Activist/Union Activist 4 = Manual Laborer/ Small Wage Earner/Farmer/Agriculture CAREER (2) for the descriptive analysis 0 = Lawyer/Politician/Political Activist 1 = Civil Servant 2 = Military 3 = Journalist/Teacher/Professor/Liberal Profession/ Business/Own Farms fTechnical/White Collar/Medical Doctor/ Engineer/Accountant 4 = Manual Laborer/ Small Wage Earner/Farmer/Agriculture 183 Experience in Prison or Exile (PRISEXIL): If a leader had experience in prison or in exile for political reasons, and not for personal reasons, it is coded as l. 0=No 1=Yes Military Service (MILEXP): Even though someone had been in obligatory military service, he is included in ’no experience’ category. The leader who was a professional military, is coded as l. O = No 1 = Professional Military Political Activity (POLACT): It decides whether someone participated in underground movements, political activity at schools, or other activities related to politics. 0=No 1=Yes Entry Mode (ENTRY): Constitutional way of entry includes the entry by the national referendum, by a council or committee, or an elected chamber or majority vote in parliament, whereas non-constitutional way comprises self-appointment (Usurpation) or military coup. O = Constitutional 1 = Non-Constitutional Foreign Experience (FOREIGN): Measurement rule depends on whether someone has been abroad for studying, working, travelling, or living for a long term. FOREIGN (l) for the descriptive analysis and FOREIGN (2) for the two-equation model. FOREIGN (l) FOREIGN (2) 0 = No 0 = None 1 = Yes 1 = Study in Foreign Countries 2 = Work in Foreign Countries 3 = Both 184 (c) Institutional Attributes Region (REGION): It is based on geographical division as well as historical or cultural similarities. As a result, even though North African countries are located in Africa, they are included in Arabic territory. North American countries are combined with European countries. 0 = Asia 1 = Africa 2 = Middle East 3 = Europe/North America 4 = Latin America ‘ 5 = Oceania Party System (PARTYSYS): O = No Party 1 = One Party 2 = Multi-Party Type of Head of Government (LEADTYPE): LEADTYPE (l) LEADTYPE (2) O = President/Military O = Prime Minister/Gen. Sec. 1 = Prime minister 1 = President/Military 2 = General Secretary Economic Freedom (ECONFREE): 1 (Not Free) - 5 (Fully Free) Population Density (POPDEN): The unit of population density as a continuous variable is 1,000 per Sq. Km. Since it is changing year by year, the value of population density is based on the year when a leader became a head of government. Homogeneity Index (HOMOGEN): It is an index that combines racial, religious, linguistic, and ethic diversity. The data during 1960 to 1965 is used since there is no big change in values. 185 Country Age (COAGECAT): 0 = Independent Since 1960 (0 - 30) l = Independent Before 1960 (31 +) Freedom Status (FREESTAT): It is an index of combination of political rights and civil rights indices. 0 = Low 1 = Medium 2 = High Urbanization (URBAN): It is related to the process of mobilization: we can divide the countries into small-states, industrialized, and developed countries. It is measured by percentage of population in cities of over 100,000 people or more. It also changes year by year. Literacy (LITERACY): Data for most countries relate to populations aged 15 and over; but in some cases, the figures are based on population over age 6. It is widely used for determining social and cultural development. d) Personal Dispositions Oral Skills (ORAL): If leaders are described by the words such as eloquent speaker, master of persuasion, brilliant orator, powerful voice, or ability to quickly grasp oral and written arguments, they have oral skills. 0=No 1=Yes Organizational Skills (ORG): If leaders are described by the words such as disposition to command with influencing purpose and boundless energy, or a man of true ability, they have organizational skills. 0=No 1=Yes 186 Language Skills (LANG): If they speak more languages other than their native language, they have language skills. 0=No 1=Yes Political Ideology (PARTYID) : A political leader is almost always possessed of some set of philosophic and political convictions that he has, for one reason or another, made his own. It is usually the same as the ideology of the party that he joins. 0 = None 1 = Liberal 2 = Independent (Center) 3 = Conservative Physical Deformity (PHYSDEF): If a leader has physiological disposition or bad health, his personality development is influenced by it. 0=No 1=Yes Parental Death or Separation in Early Age (FADIESE): 0=No 1=Yes Family or Power Connection (FAMCONN): 0=No 1=Yes (d) Exit Mode (REMOVAL): The constitutional exit includes the cases that are not involved in forceful removal, while non-constitutional exit means forceful removal from the office. The former category has automatic rule (end of term), completion of special task, defeat in election, natural death, and voluntary resignation or retirement. The latter includes the leaders who are assassinated, and deposed by military coup or other ways. Death, if nonviolent, may safely be counted as ’extra—political’, but illness is often political face-saving device for an 187 involuntary replacement. If prime ministerial changes are to be taken into account, the most straightforward criterion is to count all of them without trying to measure the exact degree to which an illness may be political (Lijphart, 1984, pp.268-269). Nonetheless, natural deaths or illness is counted as constitutional for the study. 0 = Constitutional 1 = Non-constitutional Hazard Rate Hazard Rate 1 88 APPENDIX B Hazard Rate (Life Table) Figure 21 Hazard Rate of Total Sample (N=984) Total (984) l l l, l l l l l l I, l l L, l L, l l l l l 1 l l O 2 4 6 6 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 Duration (Years) Figure 22 Hazard Rate of Censored Sample (N=882) Existing Total (882) T Censored (102) 1 1 1 1.; 1 1 L 1 l 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 L 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 Duration (Years) Table 14 Ordinary Least Squares Estimation 1 89 APPENDIX C Dependent Variable: DURATION Variable Coefficient Standard Error t-Statistic Constant 10.13656 2.54477 3.98330‘" AGE -0.1 1623 0.021 14 -5.49769"“ COLLEGE -1 .08637 0.64495 -1 .68444‘ URBAN -1 .04769 0.41331 4.53484" LAWPOL -3.38199 1.13111 -2.98997"" CIVSERV -4.27806 1 .24275 -3.44242"'" MILITAR - 1 .50243 1 .23204 -1.21946 LIBTECH -3.31387 1.10553 -2.99753”‘ POLONE 0.40314 1.30247 0.30952 POLTWO 0.8545 1 1.37807 0.62008 POLBOTH 0.81863 1 .3 8737 0.59006 F ORSTUD 1.23355 0.51625 2.38945” FORWORK 0.59810 0.58392 1.02428 F ORBOTH 1.50344 0.65585 2.29236" NONCONSTI 0.33858 0.66742 0.50729 LIBERAL 2.08950 0.90527 2.30814“ CENTRE 1.75370 1.15409 1.51955 CONSERV 2.92347 0.86769 3.36929“ OLD -1.49812 0.57361 -2.61 174'" PREZ 1 .90623 0.56955 3.34689‘” SINGLEP 3.27892 1.04722 3.13107"" MULTIP -0.09300 0.96138 -0.09673 POPDEN 0.00078 0.00094 0.83 106 HOMOGEN -0.00044 0.00108 -0.40554 LITERACY 0.0203 1 0.01 151 1.76524“ ECONSTAT -0.33774 0.28799 -1.17277 PARTFREE 0.66352 0.75779 0.87560 FULLFREE 1 .09754 1.01599 1 .08027 ASIA 0.99248 1.23797 0.80170 AFRICA 0.09237 1.28693 0.07178 MIDEAST -0.44012 1.25672 -0.35021 EURNAME 1 .37779 1.09892 1 .25377 LATINAME -0.36371 1.18041 -0.30812 Number of Observations 871 R-squared 0.20412 Corrected R-squared 0.17373 Sum of Squared Residuals 27714.8 Standard Error of the Regression 5.75087 Durbin-Watson Statistic 1.85944 Mean of Dependent Variable 5.25373 ‘ significant at .10 *" significant at .01 " significant at .05 LIST OF REFERENCES LIST OF REFERENCES Agassi, Joseph. 1986. Scientific Leadership. In Changing Conceptions of Leadership, edited by Carl F. Graumann and Serge Moscovici. New York: Springer-Verlag. Aldrich, John H. and Charles F. Cnudde. 1975. Probing the Bounds of Conventional Wisdom: A Comparison of Regression, Probit, and Discriminant Analysis. American Journal of Political Science 19: 571-608. Aldrich, John H. and Forrest D. Nelson. 1984. Linear Probabilig, Logit, and Probit Models. Beverly Hills and London: Sage Publications. Alexander, Robert J ., ed. 1988. Biographical Dictionm of Latin American and Caribbean Political Leaders. New York: Greenwood Press. Almanac of Current World Leaders. 1960-1990. Los Angeles, California. Ames, Barry. 1987. Political Survival: Politicians and Public Policy in Latin America. Berkely: The University of California Press. The Annual Obigm. 1980-1991. Chicago and London: St. James Press. Baker, Randall, ed. 1992. Public Administration in Small and Island States. West Hartford: Kumarian Press. Ballard, Elizabeth J. and Peter Suedfeld. 1988. Performance Ratings of Canadian Prime Ministers: Individual and Situational Factors. Political Psychology, Vol.9, No.2: 291—302. Beck, Carl, et a1. 1973. Comparative Communist Political Leadership. New York: D. McKay C. Bell, David S., Douglas Johnson, and Peter Morris, eds. 1990. Biographical Dictionm of French Political Leaders since 1870. New York and London: Simon & Schuter. Bienen, Henry and NIcholas Van De Walle. 1991. Of Time and Power: Leadership 190 191 Duration in the Modern World. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Bishop, Yvonne M., Stephen E. Fienberg, and Paul W. Holland. 1975. Discrete Multivariate Analysis: Theory a_r;_d Practice. Cambridge, MA. and London, England: The MIT Press. Blondel, Jean. 1980. World Leaders: Heads of Government in the Postwar Period. London and Beverly Hills: Sage Publications. Blondel, Jean. 1982. The Organizational of Governments: A Comparative Analysis of Governmental Structure. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications. Blondel, Jean. 1984. Dual Leadership in the Contemporary World: A Step towards Executive and Regime Stability? In Comparative Government and Politics, edited by Dennis Kavanagh and Gillian Peele. London: Heinemann. Blondel, Jean. 1987. Political Leadership: Towards a General Analysis. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications. Boylan, Henry. 1988. A Dictiongy of Irish Biography. 2nd ed. Gill and Macmillan, Ltd. Britannica Boon the Year: People of the Year. 1938-1992. Chicago: Encyclopedia Britannica, Inc. Bullitt, Stimson. 1977. To be a Politician. Revised edition. New Haven: Yale University Press. Bunce, Valerie. 1981. Do New Leaders make a Difference?: Executive Succession and Public Policy under Capitalism and Socialism. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Burns, James MacGregor. 1977. Wellsprings of Political Leadership. American Political Science Review LXXI, 1 (March): 266-275. Burns, James MacGregor. 1979. Leadership. New York, Hagerstown, San Francisco, London: Harper & Row, Publishers. Calvert, Peter. 1983. Politics, Power and Revolution: An Introduction to Comparative Politics. Brighton: Wheatsheaf. Calvert, Peter, ed. 1987. The Process of Political Succession. New York: St. Martin’s Press. Campbell, A., et a1. 1960. The American Voter. New York, N.Y.: Wiley. 192 Camp, Roderic A. 1979. Women and Political Leadership in Mexico. The Journal of Politics Vol.4]: 417-441. Camp, Roderic A. 1980. Mexico’s Leaders: Their Education and Recruitment. Tucson, Arizona: The University of Arizona Press. Carlyle, Thomas. 1966. On Heroes, Hero-Worship and the Heroic in Histog. Edited by Carl Anthony Niemeyer. London: University of Nebraska Press. Carter, April. 1979. Authorig and Democracy. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Cell, Charles P. 1974. Charismatic Heads of State: The Social Context. Behavior Science Research 9(4): 255-305. Charlton, Roger. 1986. Political Leadership: Executives in the Modern World. In Political Realities: Comparative Government, edited by Roger Charlton. London and New York: Longrnan Ltd. Christensen, Ronald. 1990. Log-Linear Models. New York: Springer-Verlag. The Columbia Dictiom of Political Bioggaphy. 1991. New York: Columbia University Press. Constantini, Edmond and Kenneth H. Craik. 1972. Women as Politicians: The Social Background, Personality and Political Careers of Female party Leaders. Journal of Social Issues 28(2): 217-236. Crewe, 1., ed. 1974. British Political Sociology Yearbook, Vol.1: Elites in Western Democracy. London: Croom Helm. Current Bioggaphy. 1940-1990. New York: H. W. Wilson Co. Current World Leaders: Bioggaphy and News. 1960-1990. Pasadena, California. da Graca, John V. 1985. Heads of State and Government. New York University Press. Dahl, Robert and Edward R Tufte. 1973. Size and Democracy. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Day, Alan and Henry W. Degenhardt, eds. 1980 Political Parties of th_e World. Longrnan Group, Ltd., A Keesing’s Reference Publication. de Blij, Harm J. 1967. Systematic Political Geoggaphy. New York: John Wiley & 193 Sons. Daganzo, Carlos. 1979. Multinomial Probit: The Theory and Its Application to Demand Forecasting. New York and London: Academic Press. Delpar, Helen, ed. 1974. Encyclopedia of Latin America. The McGraw-Hill. Diamond, Larry, ed. 1993. Political Culture and Democracy in Developing Countries. Boulder: L. Rienner Publishers. Dickie, John, and Alan Rake. 1973. Who’s Who in Africa: The Political Milim and Business Leaderflf Africa, London: Wheatsheaf House. Dodd, Lawrence C. 1984. The Study of Cabinet Durability: Introduction and Commentary. Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 17, No. 2 (July): 155-161. Dion, Léon. 1968. The Concept of Political Leadership: An Analysis. Canadian Journal of Political Science 1: 1-17. Dogan, Matti, ed. 1988. Comparing Pluralist Democracies: Strains on Legitimacy. Boulder and london: Westview Press. Dogan, Matti, ed. 1989. Pathways to Power: Selecting Rulers in Pluralist Democgies. Westview Press. Deutsch, Karl W. 1961. Social mobilization and Political Development. American Political Science Review 55: 493-514. Dhrymes, Phoebus J. 1986. Limited Dependent Variables. In Handbook of . Econometrics Vol.3. edited by Zvi Griliches and Michael D. Intriligator. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Ebel, Robert. 1972. Governing the City-State: Notes on the Politics of the Small Latin American Countries. Journal of Inter-American Studies and World Affairs, 14:325-346. Eckstein, Harry. 1979. Suppprt for Regime: Theories and Tests. Research Monograph No.44 . Center for International Studies. Eckstein, Harry. 1992. Regarding Politics: Essays on Political Theory, Stabilig and Change. Berkeley: University of California Press. Edinger, Lewis J. 1964. Political Science and Political Biography: Reflections on the Study of Leadership (1). The Journal of Politics Vol.26, No.2 (May): 423-439. 194 Edinger, Lewis J. 1964. Political Science and Political Biography (11). The Journal of Politics Vol.26, No.3 (August): 648-696. Edinger, Lewis J., ed. 1969. Theog and Method in Comparative Elite Analysis. New York. Edinger, Lewis J. 1974. Where are the Political Superstars? Political Science Quarterly, Vol.89, No.2 (June): 249-268. Edinger, Lewis J. 1975.. The Comparative Analysis of Political Leadership. Comparative Politics, Vol.7, No.2 (January): 253-269. Edinger, Lewis J., ed. 1976. Political Leadership in Industrial Societies: Studies of Comparative Analysis. Huntington & New York: Robert E. Krieger Publishing Company. Edinger, Lewis J. 1990. Approaches to the Comparative Analysis of Political Leadership, The Review of Politics Vol.52: 509-523. Edinger, Lewis J. and Donald D. Searing. 1967. Social Background in Elite Analysis: A Methodological Inquiry. American Political Science Review Vol.61 (June): 428-445. Edinger, Lewis J. and Donald D. Searing. 1967. Leadership: An Interdisciplinary Bibliography. In Political Leadership in Industrial Societies, edited by Lewis J. Edinger, 348-366. New York. Elderveld, Sammuel James. 1989. Political Elites in Modern Societies: Empirical Research and Democratic Theog. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Eliason, Scott R. 1993. Maximum Likelihood Estimation : Logic and Practice. A Sage University Paper. Embree, Ainslie T., ed. 1988. Encyclomrlia of Asian Histog, Vol.1 - Vol.4. New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons. Encyclomdia of World Biography. 1973. The McGraw-Hill. Erickson, Erik B. 1962. Young Man Luther: A Study in Psychoanalysis and History. New York: Norton. Etheredge, Lloyd S. 1993. The Hardball Practitioner. In Political Psychology, edited by Neil J. Kressel. New York: Paragon House Publishers. Eulau, Heinz and Moshe Czudnowski, eds. 1976. Elite Recruitment in Democratic 195 Politics: Comparative Studies Across Nations. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications. Fenno, R. 1959. The President’s Cabinet. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, Vintage Edition. F iedler, Fred E. Leadership. 1971. Pamphet and New York: General Learning Press. Field, G. Lowell, and John Higley. 1980. Eliticism. London, Boston and Henley: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Finer, S. E. 1988. The Man on Horseback: The Role of the Milim in Politics. 2nd ed. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. F isichella, Domenico. 1984. The Double Ballot System as a Weapon against Anti- System Parties. In Choosing an Electoral System: Issues and Alternatives, edited by Arend Lijphart and Bernard Grofman. New York: Praeger. Force, George T. and Jack R Van der Silk, eds. 1969. Theog and Research in the Study of Political Leadership: An Annotated Bibliography. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press. Foti, et a1. 1982. Effects of Leadership Labels and Prototypes on Perceptions of Political Leaders. Journal of Applied Psychology, 67 (June): 326-333. Gastil, Raymond D. 1974-1990. Freedom in the World. New York: Freedom House. George, Alexander. 1974. Assessing Presidential Character. World Politics 26 (June): 234-282. ' Gibbs, Cecil A. 1947. The Principles and Traits of Leadership. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 42: 267-84. Gibbs, Cecil A. 1954. Leadership. In Hgdbook of Social Psychology , Vol.2, edited by Gardner Lindsey. 877-920. Reading, Mass. Girvin, Brian. 1989. Change and Continuity in Liberal democratic Political Culture. In Contemmrm Political culture: Politicg in at Postmodern Age, edited by John R. Gibbins. London: Newburry Park. Gorvin, Ian, ed. 1989. Elections since 1945: A Worldwide Reference Commndium. Longrnan International Reference. Greenstein, Fred. 1986. Personality and Politics. In Political Leadership: A Source Book, edited by Barbara Kellerman. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh 196 Press. Grob, Leonard. 1984. Leadership: The Socratic Model. In Leadership: Multidisciplinarv Perspectivgg, edited by Barbara Kellerman, with a foreword by James MacGregor Burns. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, Inc. Gunson, Phil, Greg Chamberin, and Andrew Thompson, eds. 1991. The Dictiopary of Contemporm Politics of Central America and the Caribbean. Simon and Schuster. Gupta, Diak K. 1990. The Economics of Political Violence: The Effect of Political Instabilig: on Economic Growth. New York: Praeger. Gurr, Ted R. 1974. Persistence and Change in Political Systems, 1800-1974. American Political Science Review 68 (December): 1482-1504. Gurr, Ted R. and Muriel McClelland. 1971. Political Performance: A Twelve-Nation Study. Comparative Politics Series, Vol.2. Beverly Hills: A Sage Professional Paper. Haberman, Shelby J. 1978. Analysis of Qualitative Dar; Vol.1. New York and London: Academic Press. Hagle, Timothy M. and Glenn E. Mitchell 11. 1992. Goodness-of-F it Measures for Probit and Logit. American Journal of Political Science Vol.36, No.3 (August):762-784. Heckman, James J. 1976. The Common Structure of Statistical Models of Truncation, Sample Selection and Limited Dependent Variables and a Sample Estimator for such Models. Annals of Economic and Social Measuremenr, Vol.5, No.4: 475- 492. Hibbs, Douglas, et a1. 1982. On the Demand for Economic Outcomes: Macroeconomic Performance and Mass Political Support in the United States, Great Britain, and Germany. Journal of Politics Vol.44, No.2 (May): 426-462. Hecksner, Gunnar. 1960. The Study of Comparative Government and Politics. London: George Allen & Unwin Ltd. Hodgkinson, Christopher. 1983. The Philosophy of Leadership. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. . Hollander, Edwin. 1978. Leadership Dynamics: A Practical Guide to Effective Relationship. In Leadership, edited by J. M. Burns. New York: Harper and Row. 197 Holmes, Jack E. and Robert E. Elder, Jr. 1989. Our Best and Worst Presidents: Some Possible Reason for Perceived Performance. Presidential Studies Quarterly, 19 (2-3): 529-588. Hook, Sidney. 1986. The Eventful Man and the Event-making Man. In Political Leadership: A Source Book, edited by Barbara Kellerman. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. Huntington, Samuel P. 1991. The Third Wave: Democratization in the late Twenties Centuries. Norman and London: University of Oklahoma. Huntington, Samuel P. 1971. The Change to Change. Comparative Politics, 111, 3 (April): 283-322. Hurwitz, Leon. 1973. Contemporary Approaches to Political Stability: A Review Essay. Comparative Politics, 5 (April): 449-463. Ilchman, Warren J. and Norman T. Uphoff, eds. 1972. The Political Economy of Development: Theoretical and Empirical Contributions. Berkeley: University of California Press. Inglehart, Ronald. 1990. Culture Shift in Advanced Industrial Countries. Princeton: Princeton University Press. International Who’s Who. 1935-1992. London: Europa Publications Ltd. Jackman, Robert W. 1993. Power without Force: The Political Capacity of Nation- States. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press. Jackson, Robert and Carl Rosberg. 1982. Personal Rule in Black Africa: Prince Autocrat, Propher, Tyrant. Berkeley: University of California Press. Janda, Kenneth F. 1972. Towards the Explication of the Concept of Leadership in Terms of the Concept of Power. In Political Leadership: Readings for an Emerging Field, edited by Glenn D. Paige. New York: The Free Press. Janowitz, Morris. 1954. The Systematic Analysis of Political Biography. World Politics Vol.6, No.3 (April): 405-412. Jennings, Eugene E. 1960. An Anatomy of Leadership: Princes, Heroes, and Suxrman. New York: Harper and Brothers. Kay, Susan Ann. 1991. Introduction to the Analysis of Political Data. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. 198 Kellerman, Barbara, ed. 1986. Political Leadership: A Source Book. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. King, Anthony. 1975. Executives. In Handbook of Political Science Vol.5, edited by Fred 1. Greenstein and Nelson W. Polsby. 173-256. Addison-Wesley Publishing Company. Kingsley, David. 1976. World Urbanization 1950-1970. Westport, Conn: Greenwood Press. ' Kurian, George Thomas. 1984 & 1991. The New Book of World Rankings. New York: Facts on File Publications. Lane, Robert E. 1961. Political Life: Why People Get Involved in Politics. Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press. Lao Tzu. 1961. Tao Te Ching. Translated by John C. H. Wu. and edited by Paul K. T. Sih. New York: St. John’s University Press. Laski, H. J. 1933. Democracy in Crisis. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press. Lasswell, Harold. 1934. Psychopathology and Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Lasswell, Harold. 1948. Power and Personalig. New York: Norton. Lasswell, Harold and Daniel Lerner. 1965. World Revolutionm Elites. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press. Lasswell, Harold and Abraham Kaplan. 1950. Power and Socieg: A Framework for Political Inquiry. New haven: Yale University Press. Lee, Sidney. 1928. Principles of Biography. In Elizabethan and Other Essays. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Leonard, R L. and Richard Natkiel. 1987. World Atlas of Elections 1986. London: Hodder and Stoughton. Lerner, Daniel. 1957. Communication Systems and Social Systems: A Statistical Exploration in History and Policy. Behavioral Science 2 (October): 266-275. Lijphart, Arend. 1977. Democrgy in Plural Societies: A Comparative Exploration. New Haven: Yale University Press. 199 Li jphart, Arend. 1984. Measures of Cabinet Durability: A Conceptual and Empirical Evaluation. Comparative Political Studies, Vol 17, No. 2 (July): 265-279. Lijphart, Arend. 1992. Parliamengy versus Presidential Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Lindblom, C. E. 1968. The Policy-making Process. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall. Linz, Juan J. 1988. Legitimacy of Democracy and the Socio-Economic System of Western Democracies. In Comparing Pluralist Democracies: Strains on Legitimacy. Edited by Mattei Dogan. pp.65-113. Boulder: Westview. Lipschutz, Mark R. and R Kent Rasmussen, eds. 1986. Dictiom of African Historical Bioggiphy. Second Edition. Berkeley, Los Angeles, and London: University of California Press. Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1981. Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics. Expanded and Updated edition. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. Lipset, Seymour Martin and William Schneider. 1983. The Confidence Gap: Business, Labor and Government in the Public Mind. New York: Free Press. Little, Roderick J. A. and Donald B. Rubin. 1987. Statistical Analysis with Missing Data. New York and Toronto: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Lord, Robert G. and Myron Rush. 1980. Effects of Sex and Personality on Perceptions of Emergent Leadership, Influence, and Social Power. Journal of Applied Pachology, 65: 176-182. Lorvvin, Val R 1971. Segmented Pluralism. Comparative Politics, 3: 141-175. MacDougall, Terry Edward. 1982. Political Leadership in Contemmm Japan. Ann Arbor: Center for Japanese Studies, University of Michigan. Mackie, Thomas T. and Richard Rose. 1991. The International Almanac 0f Electoral History. 3rd ed. Washington, DC: Library of Congress Cataloging-in- Publication Data. Maddala, G. S. 1983. Limited-De ndent and itative Variables in Econometrics. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. McKelvey, Richard and William Zavonia. 1975. A Statistical Model for the Analysis 'of Ordinal Level Dependent Variables. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 4: 103-120. 200 Mainwaring, Scott. 1993. Presidentialism, Multiparty System, and Democracy: The Difficult Equation. Comparative Political Studies, Vol.26, No.2 (July): 198- 230. Makers of Modern Africa : Profiles in Histog. 1981. Published by Africa Journal Limited for Africa Books Ltd. Markus, Gregory B. and Phillip Converse. 1979. Political Environment and the Dynamics of Public Attitudes: A Panel Study. American Journal of Political Science 23 (May): 338-359. Mayser, George and Margaret Wagstaffe, eds. 1987. Research Methods for Elite Studies. Contemporary Social Research 14. London: Allen & Unwin. Merriam, Charles. 1967. Four American Pm Leaders, reprinted. F reeport: Books for Libraries. Mishler, William and Ann Hildreth. 1984. Legislatures and Political Stability: An Explanatory Analysis. Journal of Politics 46 (February): 25-59. Montesquieu. 1977. The Spirit of Laws. With an Introduction, Notes, and Appendixes, edited by David Wallace Corrinthers. Berkeley: University of California Press. Morgenthau, Hans J. and David Hein. 1983. Essays on Lincoln’s Faith and Politics, edited by Kenneth W. Thompson. Washington, DC: University of Press of America. Morrison, D. G. and H. M. Stevenson. 1971. Political Instability in Independent Black Africa: More Dimensions of Conflict Behavior Within nations. Journal of Conflict Resolution 15: 347-368. Mughan, Anthony and Samuelson C. Patterson, eds. 1991. Political Leadership in Democratic Societies. Chicago: Nelson-Hall Publishers. Neustadt, Richard. 1960. Presidential Power. New York: John Wiley. I_h_e New Africans: A Guide to the Contemmrg History of Emergent Africa and Its Leaders. 1967. London: Paul Hamlyn Ltd. New York Times Biographical Edition Service. 1970-1991. Nice, David. 1984. The Influence of War and Party System Aging on the Raking of Presidents. Western Political Quarterly, 37 (Summer): 443-455. 201 Nietzsche, Friedrich. 1969. Thus Smke Zarathustra. Translated by R. J. Hollingdale. Baltimore: Penguine Books. Nordlinger, Eric A. 1972. Conflict Regglation in Divided Societies. Cambridge, Mass: Center for International Affairs Harvard University. Paige, Glenn D. 1977. The Scientific Study of Political Leadership. New York: The Free Press. Palmer, Alan, ed. 1980. Who’s Who in Modern World : 1860-1980. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston. Palmer, Alan, ed. 1990. The Pengu_1n' Dictiom of Twentieth-Cam Histog. Third edition. Penguin Books. Panebianco, Angelo. 1988. Political Parties: Organization and Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Perlmutter, A. 1981. Political Roles and Milim Rulers. London: Cass. Pickel, Andreas. 1989. New Ask Who Should Rule: Karl Popper and Political Theory. Canadian Journal of Political Science XXII, No.1 (March): 83-105. Pimlott, Ben. 1990. The Future of Political Biography. The Political Quarterly, Vol.61, No.2 (April-June): 214-224. Pindle, David F. 1993. Head of State and Head of Government in Comparative Perspective. Presidential Studies Quarterly, Vol.108, No.2 (Summer): 271-283. Plato. 1968. The Republic of Plato. Translated, with Notes and Interpretative by Allan Bloom. New York: Basic Books Inc. Portis, E. B. 1987. Charismatic Leadership and Cultural Democracy. The Review of Politics Vol.49, No.2: 231-250. Powell, G. Bingham. 1982. Contemmm Democracy: Participatiop, Stabiliry, and Violence. Cambridge, Massachusetts: harvard University Press. Prewitt, Kenneth. 1970. The Recruitment pf Political Leaders: A Study of citizen- Politicians. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill. Pridham, Georffrey, ed. 1990. Coalitional Behavior in Theorv apdr Practice: An Inductive Mpdel for Western Eurom. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Putnam, K. J. 1964. Charisma and Political Leadership. Political Studies 12: 341- 202 354. Putnam, Robert D. 1971. Studying Elite Political Culture: The Case of Ideology. American Political Science Review Vol.65 (September): 651-681. Putnam, Robert D. 1973. The Beliefs of Politicians. New Haven: Yale University Press. - Pye, Lucian. 1985. Asian Power and Politics: The Cultural Dimensions of Authority. Cambridge, Mass: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. Rae, Douglas W. and Michael Taylor. 1979. The Analysis of Political Cleavages. New Haven and London: Yale University Press. Rake, Alan. 1992. Who’s Who in Africa: Leaders for the 19903. Netuchen, N.J.: The Scarecrow Press, Inc. Rejai, Mostafa and Kay Philips. 1988. Becoming Political Leaders. In Loyalists and Revolutionaries : Political Leaders Compared. New York : Praeger. Reich, Bernard, ed. 1990. Political Leaders of the Contemmra_ry Middle East and North Africa: A Biographical Dictiom. New York: Greenwood. The Revolution in France The Works of Edmund Burke, Vol.2. 1970. London: Henry Bohn. Riggs, Fred. 1981. The Rise and Fall of Political Development. In The Handbook of Political Behavior Vol.4, edited by Samuel L. Long. New York: Plenum Press. Rogowski, R. 1974. Rational Legitimacy. Princeton: University of Princeton Press. Rose, Richard. 1987. Ministers and Ministers: A Functional Analysis. Oxford: Claredon Press. Rose, Richard. 1993. Evaluating Presidents. In Researching the Presidency: Vital , uestions New A roaches edited by George C. Edwards 111, et a1. Pittsburgh and London: University of Pittsburgh Press. Rose, Richard and Ezra N. Suleiman, eds. Presidents and Prime Ministers. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research. Rosenbach, William E. and Robert L. Taylor. 1992. Milim Leadership: In Pursuit of Excellence. Second edition. Boulder: Westview Press. Rustow, Dankwart A. 1966. The Study of Elites: Who’s Who, When, and How. 203 World Politics Vol. XVIII, No.4 (July): 690-717. Rustow, Dankwart A. 1967. A World of Nations. Washington: Brookings Institutions. Rustow, Dankwart A. 1990. Democracy: A Global Revolution? Foreigp Affairs, 69 (Fall): 75-91. Sanders, David and Valentine Herman. 1977. The Stability and Survival of Government in Western Democracies. Acta Politig 12: 346-377. Schlesinger, Joseph A. 1966. Ambition and Politics: Political Careers in the United States. Chicago: Rand McNally. Schumpeter, Joseph. 1975. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper Colophon. Seligman, Lester G. 1950. The Study of Political Leadership. American Political Science Review Vol.44, 4 (December): 904-915. Seligman, Lester G. 1964. Leadership in New Nation. New York: Atherton Press. Singer, J. David. 1973. Man and World Politics: The Psychological Interface. Journal of Social Issues. 24 (3) (July): 127-156. California: Clio Press Ltd. Sheehan, T. 1976. Senior Esteem as a Factor of Socio-Economic Complexity. Gerontology 16: 433-40. Shils, Edward. 1982. The Political Class in the Age of Mass Society: Collectivistic Liberalism and Social Democracy. In Does Who Governs Matter? : Elite Circulation in Contemmrgy Societies, edited by Moshe M. Czudnowski, 13-34. Northern Illinois University Press. Shugart, Matthew Soberg and John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional And Electoral Dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992. Shumacher, Rose, eta1., eds. 1989. World Qu_a_li§y of Life Indicators. Santa Barbara, Siedman, R B. 1978. The Web of Group Affiliations and Conflict. New York: The Free Press. Simon, Herbert. 1965. Administrative Behavior. New York: Free Press. Sirnonton, Dean Keith. 1981. Presidential Greatness and Performance: Can We Predict 204 Leadership in the White House? Journal of Personalig, 49 (Summer): 306-323. Sirnonton, Dean Keith. 1986. Disposional Attributes of Presidential Leadership. Journal of Exp_erimental Social Psychology, 22 (Summer): 399-418. Sirnonton, Dean Keith. 1986. Presidential Personality. Journal of Personalig and Social Psychology, 51 (July): 149-160. Sirnonton, Dean Keith. 1984. Genius, Creativig, and Leadership. Cambridge, MA. : Harvard University Press. Sirnonton, Dean Keith. 1987. Why Presidents Succeed: A mlitical P§ychology of Leadership. New Haven: Yale University Press. Sinclair, Barbara. 1993. Studying Presidential Leadership. In Researching the Presidency: Vital Questions, New Approaches, edited by George C. Edwards 111, et. al., 203-232. Pittsburgh and London: University of Pittsburgh Press. Stewart, Louis H. 1977. Birth Order and Political Leadership. In A Psychological Examination of Political Leaders edited by Margaret G. Hermann, 206-236. New York: Free Press. Stogdill, Ralph Melvin. 1981. Stogdill’s handbook of Leadership: A Survey of Theory and research. Revised and expanded edition. New York: The Free Press. Suedfeld, Peter and Otto Rank. 1976. Revolutionary Leaders: Long-term Success as a Function of Changes in Conceptual Complexity. Journal of Personaliry and Social Psychology, 34 (August): 169-178. Takane, Masa’aki. 1981. The Political Elite in Japan. Berkeley: University of California. Taylor, Charles Lewis and David A. Jodice, eds. 1983. World Handbook of Political and Social Indicators 111: 1948-1982. New Haven, Conn: Yale University. Taylor, M. and V. M. Herman. 1971. Party Systems and Government Stability. American Political Science Review 65:28-37. Thompson, Kenneth W. 1984. The Dilemmas Antinomies of Leadership. In Leadership: Interdisciplimy Reflections, edited by R. S. Khare and David Little. Lanharn, New York, and London: University Press of America Inc. Thompson, Kenneth W., Hans Morgenthau, and David Hein, eds. 1983. Essays on Leadership: Compgative Insights. Lanharn: University of America. 205 Topornin, Boris N. 1990. On the classification of Socialist political system. In Contempprg Political Systems: Classifications and Tymlogies, edited by Anton Bebler and Jim Seroke. Boulder: L. Rienner. Trtunan, David B. 1951. The Governmental Process. New York. Tsuritani, Takesugu and Jack B. Gabbert, eds. 1992. Chief Executives: National Political Leadership in the United States, Mexico, Great Britain, and Japan. Pullman, Washington: Washington State University. Tucker, Robert C. 1977. Personality and Political Leadership. Political Science Quarterly, Vol.92, No.3 (Fall): 383-393. Tucker, Robert C. 1981. Politics as Leadership in Political Leadership in Democratic Societies. Columbia: University of Missouri Press. Verba, Sidney. 1961. Small Groups and Political Behavior. Princeton University Press. Vemoff, Edward, and Rirna Shore. 1987. The International Dictiom of 20th Cenrm Biography. New York : New American Library. Weisberg, Herbert F. and Jerrold G. Rusk. 1970. Dimensions of Candidate Evaluation. American Political Science Review Vol.64, No.4 (December): 1167-1185. Weisberg, Herbert F. 1978. Evaluating Theories of Congressional Roll-Call Voting. American Journal of Political Science 22: 554-577. Welsh, William A. 1970. Methodological Problems in the Study of Political Leadership in Latin America. Latin American Research Review V (Fall): 3-34. Who’s Who in Australasia and the Far East. 1989. 1st ed. International Biographical Centre. Who’s Who in the World. 1971/72-1992. Chicago, Marquis Who’s Who, Inc. Willner, Ann Ruth. 1968. The Smllbinders: Qharismatic Political Leadership. New Haven: Yale University Press. Wiseman, John A. 1991. Political Leflers in Black Africa : A Biographical Dictiom of the Major Politicians Since Indegndence. Edward Elgar Publishing Company. Wriggins, W. Howard. 1969. The Ruler’s Immrative: Strategies for Political Survival in Asia and Africa. Southern Asian Institute Series. 206 Zimmerman, E. 1979. Crisis and Crisis Outcomes: Towards a New Synthetic Approach. Euroman Journal of Political Research, 7 (March): 67-115. "711 11111111111111111111“