P IIILQIO 2' Illllllllm 3 1293 016885 This is to certify that the dissertation entitled The Impact of Firm and Market Specific Characteristics on Product Market Competition: An Empirical Analysis of the Discount Department Store Industry presented by Sheri Teresa Tice has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph 0 D 0 degree in Finance NWW aw»; Major professor Date AUEUSt 17, 1998 MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 l LIBRARY Michigan State Unlverslty PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINE return on or before date due. out DUE MTE DUE DATE DUE W APR 1 0 2005 néogflfi ma WM“ THE IMPACT OF FIRM AND MARKET SPECIFIC CHARACTERISTICS ON PRODUCT MARKET COMPETITION: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE DISCOUNT DEPARTMENT STORE INDUSTRY By Sheri Teresa Tice A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Finance 1998 ABSTRACT THE IMPACT OF FIRM AND MARKET SPECIFIC CHARACTERISTICS ON PRODUCT MARKET COMPETITION: AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF THE DISCOUNT DEPARTMENT STORE INDUSTRY By Sheri Teresa Tice Recent empirical research has documented that leverage impacts firm aggressiveness in the product market. I extend this research by studying how managerial ownership as well as other firm and market specific characteristics affect firm aggressiveness in the product market. The discount department store industry is an excellent industry to use due to a lot of heterogeneity in firm specific characteristics, essentially homogeneous merchandise, and a large number of firms in the industry. Because Wal-Mart entered many local markets, expanded through connected regions, and retained their cost advantage over the period, their entry into local markets can be seen as exogenous. Thus, the discount department store industry provides a natural experiment to study which firm and market specific characteristics determine how incumbent firms respond to a new threat, the entry of Wal-Mart, at the local market level. In a study of the expansion responses of incumbent firms in the discount department store industry to new entry by Wal-Mart into local markets, I find that private firms are less likely to expand then public firms. I also find that public firms with high managerial ownership are less likely to expand then public firms with low managerial ownership. Other results are that a higher level of debt decreases the likelihood of expansion, a higher level of focus increases the likelihood of expansion, and the more dependent a firm is on the market under attack, the greater the likelihood of expansion. I also find that Wal-Mart has a harder time gaining market share in local markets with a high fraction of stores owned by firms with high levels of managerial ownership. Wal-Mart also has a harder time gaining market share in local markets with stores owned by firms with low debt, high focus, or high profitability. Wal-Mart also has a harder time gaining market share in low Herfindahl markets. There is evidence that stores in higher Herfindahl markets are more profitable which supports co-operation within these markets and/or high switching costs in lower Herfindahl markets. Copyright by SI-IERI TERESA TICE 1998 I dedicate this dissertation and all the time and effort put forth to my parents, my husband, Barry, and my children, Brock and Crystal. My parent’s encouragement helped to continue when I felt discouraged. My husband and children supported me in this endeavor, even when it required sacrifice on their part. They also helped me to keep the important things in perspective. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to express extreme gratitude to my dissertation chairman, Dr. Naveen Khanna. His optimism, guidance, energy, patience as well as the time he invested helping me are very appreciated. I also want to thank him for the knowledge I gained from him in the seminar I took from him as well as during the dissertation process. I cannot imagine having a better mentor. I also want to thank the other members of my dissertation committee, Dr. Assem Safieddine, Dr. Peter Schmidt, and Dr. Richard Simonds, for their insightful and helpful comments throughout the dissertation process. In addition, I want to thank the other faculty members in the finance department particularly those who instructed the doctoral seminars, or invested their time in the doctoral program in other ways. I also want to thank Dr. Richard Simonds for accepting me into the doctoral program while he was chairman. I also want to thank my fellow doctoral students for their help during my stay in the program. TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ........................................................................................... ix LIST OF FIGURES .......................................................................................... x CHAPTER 1 Introduction .................................................................... l CHAPTERZ History of the Discount Department Store Industry ........ 4 2.1 Definition of the Industry .............................................. 4 2.2 Firm Locations and Movements ...................................... 6 2.3 Summary ........................................................................ 8 CHAPTER3 The Effect of High Managerial Ownership, Focus and Capital Structure On Firm Aggressiveness in the ProductMarket .......................................................... 9 3.1 Introduction .................................................................... 9 3.2 Research Design ............................................................ 13 3.3 Data ............................................................................... 17 3.4 Empirical Results ........................................................... 21 3.4.1 Explanatory Variables ........................................ 21 3.4.2 Significance of Managerial Ownership:Private Versus Public Firms ............................................. 24 3.4.3 Determinants of Private Firm Expansion .............. 34 3.4.4 The Significance of Managerial Ownership: Public Firms Only ................................................ 36 3.5 Robustness Checks ........................................................ 42 3.5.1 Operating Profit Margin Instead of Discount Sales per Square Foot ........................................... 42 3.5.2 Parent Firm Size ................................................ 42 3.5.3 Unmodeled Market Heterogeneity ........................ 44 3.5.4 The Importance of Managerial Ownership Controlling for Firm Size and Economic Growth ............................................................ 49 3.6 Summary ......................................................................... 50 CHAPTER4 Incumbent and Market Specific Determinants of an Entrant’s Penetration Into New Local Markets .............. 51 4.1 Introduction ................................................................... 51 4.2 Research Design ............................................................ 53 4.3 Data ............................................................................... 57 4.4 Empirical Results ........................................................... 61 4.4.1 New Entrant Penetration: The Importance of Incumbent Ownership ....................................... .61 4.4.2 An Indirect Test for Managerial Entrenchment ................................................... .70 4.4.3 New Entrant Penetration: Markets With Only Public Incumbent Firms ...................................... 73 4.4.4 Incumbent Penetration: Markets With Both Public and Private Firms ..................................... 87 4.4.5 Modified Herfindahls and Profitability ............... 92 4.5 Summary ........................................................................ 95 CHAPTERS Summary ......................................................................... 97 APPENDDKA Tables ........................................................................... 99 APPENDIXB Figures ......................................................................... 136 LIST OF REFERENCES .................................................................................. 149 Table 1 Table 2 Table 3 Table 4 Table 5 Table 6 Table 7 Table 8 Table 9 Table 10 Table 11 Table 12 Table 13 Table 14 Table 15 LIST OF TABLES Chains Attacked by Wal-Mart ....................................... 99 Summary Statistics: Public and Private Incumbent Firms ........................................................... 100 Simple Correlation Matrix: All Observations Public and Private ........................................................ 101 Univariate Probit: Public and Private Incumbent Firms ........................................................... 102 Univariate Probit: Public and Private Incumbent Firms Time Dummies Included ................... 103 Summary Statistics: Private Incumbent Firms .............. 104 Univariate Probit: Private Incumbent Firms ................. 105 Summary Statistics: Public Incumbent Firms ............... 106 Simple Correlation Matrix: Public Firm Observations ................................................................. 107 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbent Firms .................. 108 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbent Firms Time Dummies Included ............................................... 109 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbent Firms Using Operating Profit Margin .................................... 110 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbent Firms Parent Size Added ........................................................ 111 Univariate Probit: Public and Private Incumbents Regional Dummies ........................................................ 112 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbents Regional Dummies ........................................................ 113 ix Table 16 Table 17 Table 18 Table 19 Table 20 Table 21 Table 22 Table 23 Table 24 Table 25 Table 26 Table 27 Table 28 Univariate Probit: Public and Private Incumbents State Population Changes ............................................. 114 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbents State Population Changes ............................................. 115 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbents State Population Changes Herfindahl Instead of Market Share ................................................................. 116 Univariate Probit: The Importance of Ownership Controlling for Firm Size, and Economic Growth ......... 117 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share as a Function of Ownership in a Local Market ........................................................................... 118 Summary Statistics: All Markets ................................... 119 Summary Statistics: Markets With All Public Incumbents .................................................................... 120 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share as a Function of Ownership in a Local Market: Market and Firm Size Controls ..................................... 121 Constrained Least Squares Spline Regressions Testing for Differences in Slope Coefficients for Different Ownership Groups: Market and Firm Size Controls Added ..................................................... 122 OLS Spline Regression: Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share as a Function of Different Ownership Groups: Market and Firm Size Controls Added ............ 123 Simple Correlation Matrix for Independent Variables Using Public Incumbent Markets .................. 124 Summary Statistics: Markets With All Public Incumbents ................................................................... 125 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share at Year +2: Markets With Only Public Firms: Dependent Variable is Penj ......................................... 126 Table 29 Table 30 Table 31 Table 32 Table 33 Table 34 Table 35 Table 36 Table 37 Summary Statistics: Markets With All Incumbents .................................................................. 127 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share at Year +4: Markets With Only Public Firms ................................................................. 128 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share in Year +2 as a Fraction of Stores In Market in Year -1: Markets With Only Public Firms ................................................................. 129 Simple Correlation Matrix for Independent Variables Using All Local Markets ............................... 130 Summary Statistics: All Local Markets ......................... 131 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share: All Markets No Debt Ratio, No Focus Variable .............................................................. 132 OLS Regression Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share: All Markets. No Debt Ratio ................... 133 Summary Statistics ........................................................ 134 OLS Regressions Explaining State Profitability And Herfindahls ............................................................ 135 Figure 1 Figure 2 Figure 3 Figure 4 Figure 5 Figure 6 Figure 7 Figure 8 Figure 9 Figure 10 Figure 11 Figure 12 Figure 13 Figure 14 LIST OF FIGURES Standard Discount Department Store Salesper Person (U.S.) .................................................................... 136 Fraction of 1975 Industry Sales By Top Five Chains ........................................................................... 137 Fraction of 1995 Industry Sales By Top Five Chains ........................................................................... 137 Top Ten Firms Based on Sales ...................................... 138 Wal-Mart 1975 Store Locations .................................... 139 Wal-Mart 1985 Store Locations .................................... 140 Wal-Mart 1990 Store Locations .................................... 141 Wal-Mart 1996 Store Locations .................................... 142 Wal-Mart and Sky City 1981 Store Locations ............... 143 Wal-Mart and Sky City 1990 Store Locations ............... 144 Wal-Mart and TG&Y Store Locations 1977 .................. 145 Wal-Mart and TG&Y Store Locations 1986 ................... 146 Wal-Mart and Duckwall 1975 Store Locations .............. 147 Wal-Mart and Duckwall 1996 Store ocations ................ 148 xii CHAPTER] Introduction Recently, financial economists have started to examine the relationships between firm characteristics and product market competition. In the capital structure area, one group of theoretical models predicts that increases in financial leverage “softens” product market competition while another group of theoretical models predicts that increases in financial leverage “toughens” product market competition. In the incentive contract area, a group of theoretical papers hypothesize that incentive contracts can influence the level of managerial aggressiveness in the product market and entry decisions. On the empirical side, a couple of recent papers have documented a link between changes in a firm’s capital structure and subsequent product market competition. Nonetheless, there are many unanswered questions regarding the impact of firm specific characteristics such as managerial ownership, capital structure and diversification on product market competition. There are also unanswered questions regarding the impact of market specific characteristics on product market competition. For example, it is 2 easier or harder for a new entrant to gain market share in a high Herfindahl market versus a low Herfindahl market? High Herfindahl markets may provide profit opportunities, however, the firms in these markets may have developed effective barriers to entry and expansion. This dissertation is an empirical attempt to broaden our understanding in these areas. I use the discount department store industry as a laboratory to examine the impact of firm and market specific characteristics on product market competition. This industry provides a natural experiment for several reasons. First, there are a large number of firms with heterogeneous characteristics. Second, these firms compete locally. Third, there is essentially a homogeneous product. Fourth, Wal-Mart expanded dramatically throughout the United States presenting a severe competitive threat to the many regional chains in the industry. This allows me to examine how firms respond to a virtually identical threat holding industry constant. In Chapter 2 the industry that is used to conduct this analysis, the discount department store industry, is defined and described. Maps showing store locations are used to demonstrate the regional nature of many of the firms as well as Wal-Mart’s dramatic expansion. The maps are also used to show differences in firm responses to Wal-Mart entering their local markets. Chapter 3 examines the firm and market specific determinants 3 of incumbent firms’ decisions to expand or not when Wal-Mart enters their local markets. The fundamental question addressed in this chapter is: Do different firm and market specific characteristics lead to different investment decisions in the product market when incumbents face the same threat? Chapter 4 examines the firm and market specific determinants of Wal-Mart’s market share gains after entering local markets. The fundamental question addressed in this chapter is: Which firm and market specific characteristics does Wal-Mart find leads to easier market penetration? An indirect test of agency theory and the entrenchment hypothesis is also done to examine the relationship between managerial ownership and Wal-Mart’s ability to gain market share after entering a market. An examination of the link between market concentration and profitability is also done. CHAPTERZ History of the Discount Department Store Industry 2.1 Definition of the Industry The discount department store industry was first defined by a trade journal called Discount Merchandiser in 1961. They defined a discount department store as “a departmentalized retail establishment utilizing many self-service techniques to sell hard goods, health-and-beauty aids, apparel and other soft goods and other general merchandise. It operates at uniquely low margins. It has a minimum annual volume of $1,000,000 ($500,000 in the 1970’s) and is at least 10,000 square feet in size.” The discount department store industry grew rapidly. They took sales away from department stores as they were a cheaper alternative for many items. They also took sales away from variety stores as they provided a larger product assortment. More recently, they are adding food selections and are attempting to take sales away from grocery stores. Figure 1 demonstrates this by showing standard discount department store sales per person in the United States. A list was compiled of all of the discount store chains that Wm had on the “Leading Discounters” list in at 5 least one year during the time period of 1975 - 1996. To be on the “Leading Discounters” list they had to have sales of at least $100 million (850 million in the 1970’s). This procedure eliminated the very small “mom and pop” type chains which have very little public information available.l A trade journal called W Discoooi Department Storos was then used to determine store locations for all of these chains for each year in which they operated in the industry during the period of 1975 - 1996.2 Thus, a discount department store chain had to be on the “Leading Discounters” list in Qiscouot Mcrchondisor and located in Ihe Dirootory of Disoount Deoartmeot Stores to be included in the sample. At the beginning of 1975, there were 105 firms with at least one discount department store chain. By the beginning of 1996, there were 34 firms with at least one discount department store chain. Not only were there fewer players in 1996, but the stores and sales were concentrated in the largest firms. Figures 2 & 3 show the fraction of discount department store sales achieved by the top five firms in the industry ranked by sales in 1975 and 1995 respectively. It is evident that the larger firms are capturing a ‘memnmhmemmmmmwmmfle Onlystandrd discount depttment stores were used. No manbership/warehmse clubs or hyper-markets were included in thesample. 2Iftwoormorechainsvrmeovvnedlavyfliesumefirmatthesnmetime,theywerecombinedintooneehain. 'Ihenetresultwasll3diains. 6 much larger fraction of industry sales in the United States in 1995 than in 1975. In addition to the concentration increase that occurred in this industry, there was also a change in the largest players. Figure 4 shows the ten largest firms in the sample, based on sales, in 1975, 1985, and 1995. As can be seen, there was a lot of change in the names of the firms that are ranked in the top ten based on sales. 2.2 Firm Locations and Movements Many of the discount department store chains in the industry were regionally located. In 1975, Kmart was the only true national chain. In 1996, Kmart, Wal-Mart and to a more limited extent Target and Marshalls could be considered national chains. The chain that experienced the most dramatic growth during the period 1975 to 1996 was Wal-Mart. Wal-Mart grew from a regional chain to the largest retailer in the United States during the period. Figures 5,6,7 & 8 show Wal-Mart store locations at the beginning of 1975, 1985, 1990 a 1996 respectively.’ It is interesting to examine the behavior of incumbent chains when Wal-Mart entered their local markets. Figure 9 shows store locations for Sky City and Wal-Mart at the beginning of 1981. As can be seen, Sky City was a regional discount department store chain. Wal-Mart entered one of Sky City’s markets between the 7 beginning of 1980 and 1981. By the beginning of 1990 Wal-Mart had blanketed Sky City’s markets with stores. Store locations at the beginning of 1990 for Wal-Mart and Sky City are shown in Figure 10. Sky City, unlike Wal-Mart, did not change store locations much during the period of 1981 — 1990. In 1990, Sky City exited the industry. Figure 11 shows store locations for TG&Y and Wal-Mart at the beginning of 1977. Wal-Mart and TG&Y started competing between the beginning of 1976 and 1977 when TG&Y entered the industry by converting variety stores to discount department stores. By the beginning of 1986, Wal-Mart was competing in many of TG&Y’s markets. Figure 12 shows store locations at the beginning of 1986. TG&Y, unlike Sky City did expand against Wal-Mart. However, in 1986, TG&Y also exited the discount department store industry. Duckwall was already competing with Wal-Mart in a couple of markets at the beginning of 1975. Figure 13 shows store locations at the beginning of 1975 for Duckwall and Wal-Mart. Unlike the other two chains, Duckwall has been able to survive in the industry and still exists today. Duckwall primarily expanded away from Wal-Mart by going West in the late 1970’s and 1980’s. Store locations for both chains at the beginning of 1996 are shown in Figure 14. When looking at Figure 14, it is evident that Wal-Mart has not penetrated some of the markets that Duckwall is located in ThemapsshowallofthesdigitzipcodesmwhichWal-Mm'thadatleast1staeindiegivenyear. 8 to the same extent that they penetrated some of the markets that the other two competitors were located in. The rest of the dissertation examines both sides of the strategic interaction. First, which firm and market specific characteristics determine incumbents’ expansion decisions as a response to Wal-Mart’s entry into their local markets? Second, which markets does Wal-Mart perceive are weaker and penetrate quicker? 2.3 Summary In this chapter, the discount department store industry was defined. Over the past twenty years there has been consolidation both in the form of fewer players, as well as a change in the largest firms within the industry. Most of the firms in the industry over the past twenty years have been regionally located. Firms exhibit different responses when they are attacked by Wal-Mart at the local market level. It appears that some responses may be better at curtailing Wal-Mart’s penetration into a firm’s local markets. CHAPTER3 The Effect of High Managerial Ownership, Focus and Capital Structure On Firm Aggressiveness in the Product Market 3.1 Introduction Financial economists have recently started researching the linkages between firm characteristics and product market competition. Recent empirical research has investigated how changes in capital structure affect firm behavior in the product market.4 This chapter of my dissertation builds on previous research by examining the impact of ownership structure as well as capital structure and other firm and market specific factors as determinants of firm responses when facing a severe new competitive threat. Fershtman and Judd (1987) show that incentive contracts affect the level of managerial aggressiveness in the product market. They show that in oligopolistic situations, owners can make managers produce more (than in conventional oligopoly models) by giving them contracts that put weight not only on profits but also on sales. This finding is especially meaningful in industries with ‘ For ample, see Phillips (1995), Chevalier (1995), and Opler and TM (1994). 9 10 higher strategic substitutability.’ Existing papers that attempt to empirically document the relationship between incentive contracts and firm aggressiveness do so indirectly. Kedia (1997) and Aggarwal and Samwick (1997) test to see whether firms whose outputs are strategic substitutes provide contracts with low managerial ownership.6 Both of these papers document that as suggested by theory, the weight in the contract on firm profits reduces with the extent of substitutability. In this paper I test the relationship between managerial ownership and firm aggressiveness directly. I look at the actual expansion decisions of competing firms, with different levels of managerial ownership, in response to a common threat. If managerial ownership is an important determinant of firm aggressiveness, then we should be able to observe that firms with higher ownership are less aggressive then competitors with lower ownership when facing the same threat. I also examine the role other firm specific characteristics play in shaping a firm’s behavior in the product market. A firm’s capital structure, degree of focus, profitability, size, market share, and dependence on the market may also affect their response to a new competitive threat. 5Reitman(l993)extendsthisreeeardibyshowingdlatstockopfionscanbeusedtocmtrolthedegreeof aggression. ‘Theimplicatimismatlowa'weightmownashipmflatesmmhighaweightmodlava‘iables, possl‘blesalesrewedasmggestedbyFershtmanandJudd(l987). 11 The data set that I use is from the discount department store industry. From 1975-1996 Wal-Mart grew from a small regional discount department store chain to being the largest retailer in the U.S. During their expansion across the U.S. they competed with 69 different discount department store chains. Because discount department stores carry essentially homogeneous merchandise yet are surprisingly heterogeneous in firm level characteristics, this data set provided me the opportunity to study the impact of managerial ownership and other firm specific characteristics on incumbent firm decisions keeping the industry, product and threat relatively constant across all observations. Also, since Wal-Mart expanded across the U.S. through connected regions, their entry into a market can be seen as exogenous. This avoids some of the endogeneity problems faced by other studies in this area that attempt to see if one firm decision causes another firm decision. For example, Chevalier (1995) examines whether firms undertaking a LBO are weaker in the subsequent period than their less levered rivals.7 First I look at extreme levels of ownership by comparing expansion decisions of privately held and publicly traded firms as a response to new entry by Wal-Mart. I find that private firms are less likely to expand in response to the new threat than public firms. 7Also,seePhillips(1995)andKovenockandPhillips(1997). Chevalia'uiestoconu'olforpossible mdogmeityoftheLBOdecisionbydoingmerohlsmwchecks. KovulockandPhillipsuseanvo-stage 12 However, these two organizational forms differ on other dimensions like access to capital, and inherent differences on the amount of information that is available to the market. To control for this, I run similar tests on the sub-sample of public firms. This allows me to check whether it is managerial ownership that is driving the results for the private firms. I find that public firms with higher levels of managerial ownership are less likely to expand then public firms with lower levels of managerial ownership. This suggests that high ownership is making both public and private firms less aggressive in the product market when facing a new competitive threat. Other significant results are that firms with lower amounts of debt in their capital structure are more likely to expand as are more focused firms. Firms with a high market share in a market, as well as firms that are highly dependent on a market are also more likely to expand in that market. The more profitable firms are also more likely to expand as a response to new entry by Wal-Mart into their markets. These results are robust to changes in the profitability measure, the addition of regional dummies, and the addition of time dummies. The remainder of this chapter is organized as follows: Section 3.2 discusses the research design. Section 3.3 describes the data. Section 3.4 presents the methodology and empirical results. Section 3.5 presents robustness checks, and Section 3.6 is the summary. regressimwcmuolfamispoblan. 13 3.2 Research Design During the period of 1975-1996 Wal-Mart transformed itself from a regional chain consisting of 125 stores in eight states to a national chain consisting of 2,234 stores in all fifty states.8 Figures 5 through 8 show Wal-Mart store locations at the beginning of 1975, 1935, 1990 and 1996 respectively.’ When looking at the maps it is apparent that Wal-Mart expanded throughout the U.S., and that they expanded through connected regions. Competition between discount department stores takes place at the local level. Following Chevalier (1995) the United States is broken down into local markets. The local markets used in this study are 862 3-digit zip code areas. R n M N 11 Z' Eiooor defines the five digits of the zip code. The first digit of the zip code identifies the geographic region of the country. The second digit identifies a portion of the geographic region. The third digit identifies a sectional center or multi-coded city within that portion of the geographic region. A sectional center is usually the natural center of local transportation and serves the smaller post offices surrounding it. A multi-coded city is a main city post office that serves post office branches within a city. The fourth and fifth digits in the zip code identify the individual post office branches 'Numberofstoredataisfi'omDiscotherdimdisa. Loeationsofstoresbystatesisfi‘om'IheDh‘ectg of Discount Meat Stores. Themapsshowallofthes digitzipcodesinwhich Wal-mhadatleastonestoreindlegivalyear. The store locations came from The Directgy of Discmmt Meat Stores. 14 that are served by the sectional center or multi-coded city office. Because the sectional centers and multi-coded cities are usually the natural center of local transportation, the three-digit zip code area served by them is felt to be a reasonable economic market. In 1975 Wal-Mart had discount department stores in 45 of the 862 local markets. By the beginning of 1996, Wal-Mart had entered another 655 local markets for a total of 700 markets.10 During the period of 1975-1996, 69 different discount department store chains owned by 76 different firms competed against Wal-Mart in the United States at the local market level.ll A couple of these were national chains, while the rest were regional. These chains were surprisingly heterogeneous in characteristics at the firm level. The local markets differed not only on which of the chains were competing but also on total number of stores. While some markets were being served by only one chain, in other markets competition between 6-7 different chains was not uncommon. One of the problems well recognized in the literature is that firm specific characteristics may be caused by the same exogenous factors that determine investment decisions. Hence, a major concern in developing the research design of the paper is to minimize this endogeneity problem. I adopt the methodology used in Opler and Titman (1994). Instead of trying to establish whether '° In calendar 1996 and 1997, Wal-Mart continued to expmld in the United States. 15 one decision (say a LBO) causes another decision (say investment), firm specific characteristics are measured prior to an external threat. Subsequent investment decisions are then examined to see if any of these characteristics determined the subsequent investment decisions.12 In this paper, the threat is new entry by Wal-Mart into a local market where some other firms in the discount department store industry are incumbents. The investment decision is expansion or no expansion by each incumbent firm i in the local market j when first invaded by Wal-Mart. A time line illustrating the empirical set-up is shown below. Firm and mkt specific Wal-Mart variables measured enters mkt j L i 1 1 -1 0 +1 +2 Year < D Incumbent firm i’s expansion decision measured fiom Year -1 to Year +2 Year 0 is defined as the beginning of the year in which Wal-Mart first has a store in 3-digit zip code market j. The firm and market specific variables are measured at the beginning of Year —1 to avoid spurious correlation between the variables and the subsequent “LBO’s,spin-ofl‘s,andgoingpublicwerenot cmmtedasfirmdlmgeshaemlyacquisitionswere counted. 12AshIOpla'andTitrnlm(1994),!1113implicitlyassmnesthatexantefirmspecificcharacteristicsare exogenous. l6 expansion decision. If they are flow variables (from the income statement), they are measured over the fiscal year ending at the beginning of Year -1.‘3 If they are non-flow variables (balance sheet items and market specific variables), the values are measured at the end of the fiscal year which is at the beginning of Year -1.“ The economic activity variable and incumbent expansion decisions are examined from Year -1 to Year +2. This data set has a number of advantages. First, given that most of the local markets experienced entry by Wal-Mart during the period examined I am able to generate a large number of observations where incumbent firms face an exogenous threat. Second, I am able to keep the threat constant, since I only study the response of incumbents to new entry by Wal-Mart into their local markets.” Third, discount department stores carry essentially non- differentiated merchandise and are thus homogeneous in that respect. This reduces problems of differential product quality across firms. Also, this data set provides me with a reliable measure of profitability “sales per square foot” for both public and private chains. This enables me to include privately owned firms in many of the tests. Since this data set permits us to keep industry, product 13Inthisindustry, ahnostalloftheretailershadafiscnlyearendinghnuary3l ofthegivenyearoverthe timeperiodexamined. l"Iheexceptionha'eisLBO’s. lfafirmmdamtaLBOintheyearspreceedingYeu—l,dlmitwas treatedasaLBOfirminYec—l. l7 and threat constant across all observations, I can develop reasonably clean tests on how different firm and market characteristics affect incumbent firms’ responses to Wal-Mart’s entry. Normally, you might not expect firms to expand in response to new entry if the local markets are in equilibrium. This industry, however was growing due to the fact that the industry was taking sales away from other retailers. The question being addressed is thus, “Which chains are trying to grab part of the growing market in the face of Wal-Mart’s entry?” 3.3 Data A trade journal called Discount Merohondiser was used to identify major discount chains during the period of 1975 - 1996. They define a discount department store as “a departmentalized retail establishment utilizing many self-service techniques to sell hard goods, health-and-beauty aids, apparel and other soft goods and other general merchandise. It operates at uniquely low margins, has a minimum annual volume of $1 million ($500,000 in the 1970’s), and has at least 10,000 square feet of total space.” A list was compiled of all of the discount store chains that Disoount Mmhonojm had on the “Leading Discounters” list in at least one year during the time period of 1975 - 1996. To be on the “Leading ‘5hembeugmdthnannaflaWal-Mmmecfiayearsposedadifl’eandlreatdlmahrgaWal-Mtt lateron. [canolfm'fllisdlrmghtimemdregiondmnmies 18 Discounters” list they had to have sales of at least $100 million ($50 million in the 1970’s). This procedure eliminated the very small “mom and pop” type chains which have very little public information available." A trade journal called MW Sims was then used to determine store locations for all of these chains for each year in which they operated in the industry during the period of 1975 — 1996.'7 Thus, a discount department store chain had to be on the “Leading Discounters” list in Discount W and located in [he Disootozy of Discount Deonrtment mm to be included in the sample. The net result was store location data for 113 discount chains. The “Alphabetical Index” of the directory lists all cities within each state in which a discount chain has at least one store open or any planned openings at the beginning of the year." Each of the cities was then converted to a 9 The first digit ofa zip code identifies the five-digit zip code.I geographic region of the country. The second digit tells you the portion of a State or States the area is located in. The third digit is "Va-ietysta’esaresmallu'thandiscmmtdepamnmtstoresandarenotinthe‘lheD_n_eg_ory' ofDiscount Went Stores (r the sample. Also, ally standard discomt deputmmt states were used. No membership/warehouse clubs or hyper-markets were included in the sample. "Iftwoormoredlainswereownedbyafimatdlesmnefimedleywaecanbinedintoonedlain. The netresultwas113 chains. " For 1984- 1986 no “Alphabetical lndex”exists,sothe extended listings of The gm of Diseamt MaltStoresforthoseyearswereusedtoemmictashnilarlist. ‘TheRanndaniy1996ZJioCodanlgwasusedfirsttocmvertcitiestozipcodes. Ifacityeouldnot beformd,d1e'l‘imeZioCodeDirecto_r_y1994editionwasused. Ifthereweremorethentwocitieswidlthe same nameinthe same state the extended listings of The Directgy of Discmmt Merit Storeswas medtodetexminethecorrecteounty.Oncetheem'reeteamtywasknownmecmeetcitycouldbe idaltified. Aficdfisprocessathyfiacdonofzipcodescaddnotbefmmdfleasdml%) 19 the sectional center of a multi-coded city, and the last two digits tell you the individual post office branch.20 The zip codes were then plotted on a map using a mapping program. A visual inspection of Wal-Mart’s movements and other firms’ expansion and retrenchment decisions was then possible. To generate local markets, the last two digits of the zip codes were dropped generating 3-digit zip code area markets. Within the time period of 1975-1996, 862 of these local 3-digit zip code markets had at least one discount store during at least one year and 69 of the 113 chains competed with Wal-Mart in at least one of the local markets. Between 1976 and 1994, Wal-Mart entered 540 of these local 3-digit zip code markets and attacked 59 different chains owned by 62 different firms. The trade journals give the chain name and the immediate company that owns the discount store chain. Oftentimes the immediate company that owns a chain is a 100% owned subsidiary of a parent company. In order to determine if there was a parent firm, and if a company was privately held or publicly traded, Dun & Bradstreet’s Wm WM Affiiiojions Who Owns Whom, and Wards Business Directory were used in that order. A firm was classified as “public” if their stock, or the stock of their parent was traded on the NYSE, ASE or in the OTC market. Otherwise they were classified as “private”. There ThisdefinitimofthemenningofzipeodesisfimndleRanndNLlly1996ZioCodeFinder. 20 was sometimes a one or two year lag between when ownership actually changed and when it showed up in one of the above sources. The NYSE, ASE, and OTC Daily Stock Price Records books were checked to see if a firm was still trading on January 1 of a given year. This way it could be identified in which year the ownership changes occurred. When the name of the firm owning a chain changed, Discount Merchandiser was used to identify the underlying reason for the name change. Each name change was identified as being due to a LBO, being acquired by another firm, going public, a spin-off from a parent or to simply to change the firm’s image.“ The 69 chains that competed with Wal-Mart between 1975-1996 were owned by 76 different firms during the years of competition with Wal-Mart.22 The 76 firms consisted of 40 firms that were always public, 21 that were always private, 13 that were both (not at the same time) , and 2 that were foreign held during the 1975 - 1996 period. The foreign held firms were dropped from the sample, as detailed information regarding ownership was not easily available. Discount sales per square foot came from The Directory of W. Occasionally total square footage was not shown for a given firm for a given year. The average square "wedidmsdmmsfir 1981- 1989wereusedtoverifythatdlisjrocessdid notomitanymergasaLBO’s. 22LBO’s, spin-offsmdgoingpublicwerenotco‘mtedasfirmdimgeshaeonlyacquisitimswa'e counted. 21 footage of a store for that firm in a surrounding year was then used to determine sales per square foot.”3 The number of stores in the discount department store industry and sales per square foot (based on selling space) for the discount department store industry came from W. Total parent firm sales for both public and private firms were found in the WW, The Dirooiory of Coroorato Affiliaiions Who Owns Whom, and flasds Business Direotosy in that order. Firm level discount sales came from The Direotory of Discount Deoartmeni Stores except for 1975 through 1978 where they came from W. Insider ownership was taken from Proxy Statements or Volne Lino Investmsnt Survey.24 A firm’s total debt to total assets ratio and operating profit margin came from Compustat. 3.4 Empirical Results 3.4.1 Explanatory Variables Several factors other than managerial ownership can be identified that might be expected to contribute to the expansion decision by public firms in a local market. Several theoretical models hypothesize that capital structure will impact a firm’s behavior in the product market. One group of models predicts that 23Inaflrweusos,(pa'ticulal'lyobservationsfi'omthe l970’s),sales or= .05 w own-,4 .05 to .25 = 0 if w opr is < .05 = w oij,.1 minus .05 if .05 < or = w own-,1 < .25 = .20 if w oijn > or = .25 woijfl over .25 =0ifw oijfl <.25 = wopr minus .25 if w opr > or = .25 The results are shown in Table 25. The slope coefficient is negative on the ownership measures in all three groups in the piecewise regression. However, it is only statistically significant in the less than 5% ownership group. 73 4.4.3 New Entrant Penetration: Markets With Only Public Incumbent Firms This section is an attempt to determine why Wal-Mart finds firms with lower managerial ownership to be easier prey in the product market. Only markets with all public incumbent firms at the beginning of Year —1 are used, as debt ratios are only available f for public firms. Firms with lower managerial ownership may have more debt in their capital structures as debt can be used as an incentive device to lower the agency problem. The use of debt, however, may increase predatory behavior on the part of the other competitors.72 Wal-Mart may find markets with high debt firms to have “softer” product market competition. However, there also is a strand of literature that argues that firms may take on more debt to commit to more aggressive output behavior in the product market.73 Hence, Wal- Mart could find competition to be “tougher” when there are a large fraction of high debt firms in a local market. All of these papers suggest that debt is a choice variable. This may not be the case. There is some evidence in the sample that debt may be used as an incentive device. Table 26 shows the simple correlation matrix for the variables in the sample with the 233 public incumbent firm observations. As can be seen in Table 26, markets whose stores are ”SeeforexampleBoltonmdeiai-fitein0990) ”Seefor-t-pleBranderandLewis 74 owned by firms with low managerial ownership are markets whose stores are owned by firms that use more debt. Firms with lower managerial ownership may be more diversified. They may be “building empires” to satisfy their own perquisites. There is some evidence in the sample that this is the case. Markets whose stores are owned by firms with low managerial ownership are markets whose stores are owned by firms that have a lower fraction of their sales coming from discounting. Theoretical work differs on its predictions here as to how this will impact the “toughness” of product market competition. One group of models predicts that failing divisions may be subsidized sub-optimally by more profitable divisions.74 This would argue that diversified firms may fight longer and harder than focused stand-alone firms. Stein (1997) argues that firms that are diversified into related areas can more easily judge relative profitability and may take funds away from divisions where future prospects are relatively poor. This would imply that diversified firms could retrench quicker when threatened. It is also possible that either high or low ownership firms tend to be located in high Herfindahl markets. In this sample, high Herfindahl markets are negatively correlated with the level of managerial ownership of firms in the markets. It is not clear if Wal-Mart will gain a higher or lower market share in high "for exmnple see Meyer, Milgrom and Roberts (1992) and Scharfstein and Stein (1997) 75 Herfindahl markets. If the incumbents cooperate we would expect higher penetration. Wal-Mart may expect collusion in these markets, and the incumbents do collude. If the incumbents have mechanisms to block entry and expansion we would expect lower penetration in high Herfindahl markets. With respect to low Herfindahl markets, it may be easier for Wal-Mart to expand in these markets, as it may be easier to eliminate marginal performers A‘— due to Wal-Mart’s cost advantage. On the other hand, it may be harder for Wal-Mart to penetrate low Herfindahl markets as switching costs would be expected to be higher. Competitors may be more efficient in these markets, and the marginal benefits would be low to customers to drive farther to get better prices. This effect may be particularly pronounced in local markets with higher income populations. It is also possible that other ownership incentive contracts which can affect output and entry decisions may also impact the penetration of Wal-Mart into local markets that consist of firms that have such contracts. Hence, managerial ownership may still determine new entrant penetration even after controlling for the other variables discussed.” Other variables that will be used as control variables as they may impact the ability of Wal-Mart to gain market share are incumbent firm profitability, firm size, firm dependency on the 76 local market under attack, and the size of the market. The new variables are defined as follows: w feel: The weighted average focus of the firms with at least one store in local market j at the beginning of Year —1. The weights were calculated by determining what fraction of the total stores in local market j firm i had at the beginning of Year —1. Focus is calculated as discount sales divided by total firm sales for the fiscal year ending at the beginning of Year —1 for firm i.76 This variable is reported in decimal form. w debt,: The weighted average total debt ratio of the firms with at least one store in local marketj at the beginning of Year —1. The weights were calculated by determining what fraction of the total stores in local market j firm i had at the beginning of Year —1. The total debt ratio is calculated as total assets (Compustat Item #A6) minus Stockholder Equity (Compustat Item #A216) divided by total assets (Compustat Item #A6). It is thus the book value of total debt divided by the book value of total assets and was calculated at the 7’ For exanpleseeKhm(l998)andFershtman andJudd(1987) ”Somethnesthisratiowasgreaterthm l foragivmfirmiastotalfirmsalesmddiscmmtsalmcamefran difl‘erentsomces. Whmevcrthishappmedlwasused. —_'r-—_ '- I ~11 77 beginning of Year —1 for firm i." This variable is reported in decimal form. w ssqj: This is a measure of profitability. The weighted average inflation adjusted sales per square for the firms with at least one store in local market j at the beginning of Year -1. Inflation adjusted sales per square foot is measured in 1974 dollars for the fiscal year ending at the beginning of Year —1 for firm i."a mod herfj: This is a measure of market concentration. It is calculated as the sum of the squared market shares of the firms in each local market j. The market share of each firm in a local market j is defined as the fraction of stores in the local market owned by firm i.” The first set of tests in this section will use “penj” as the dependent variable. The model specification to be estimated using OLS is as follows: Pen-,2 = a + B: W f°°i.-l + 132 W debts-1 + B: W OWPi-l + 54‘” dept-1 + 135 W “Qt-I + Bo ploplgm + [37 mod herfi,.1 + B; lustre-,1 + B. annual time dummies + a,- "MfirmnflecksandSE.NidmlscmldnotbefmmdonCompuflat. Thisratiowascalaflatedfian statements located in Moody’s Industrial Manuals instead. 7' Due to the low margins and homogenous goods in this indmIry, higher turnover lends tohigher grofitability. This measure of profitability is the only one available for both public and private firms. Recallthattheverysmalldiainsmenotmthesample. Onlychainsthatmetthesizea'itciastatedinthe dataswtiona'einthesample. 78 The level of debt is not available for privately held firms. As mentioned earlier, Wal-Mart entered 488 local markets between 1981 and 1994. All local markets were dropped from the sample that had any foreign held firms in them, or that had no stores in them at the beginning of Year —1. This left 471 local markets. About half of these markets, 233 to be exact, had only public firms in them at the beginning of Year —1 and had debt and ownership data available for all firms in the local market at the beginning of Year -1. The first few specifications are run using these 233 local markets. Table 27 shows the summary statistics for all of the variables used in this first specification. Table 28 shows the estimation results for three models. OLS estimation was used in all of the models.” Annual year dummies were included in all three of the model estimations, but their coefficients are not shown. In all three models the Cook-Weisberg (1983) test rejects the null hypothesis of no homoskedasticity at 5%. Hence, the standard errors used in all three models are White’s heteroskedasticity robust standard errors. Model I is the full model where the estimation is run using all of the variables. The results show that Wal-Mart has an easier time penetrating local markets if the incumbent firms have high debt levels prior to new entry by Wal-Mart into local market j. This ”SincemedepcndmtvariableisbmmdedbetweenwomdoneaTobitestimationprocedmemightbe appuprime. I-lowever,observationsateitherextremearerare,soOLS estimationisusedasitiseonsidaed 79 result is significant at less than 1% and is consistent with predatory behavior on the part of the new entrant. A ten percent increase in the weighted average debt ratio of the market will lead to about a 7% increase in Wal-Mart’s penetration rate. Wal-Mart also has an easier time gaining market share in local markets that have higher Herfindahls prior to Wal-Mart entering, controlling for market size. This result is also significant at less than 1%. Ex-ante it is unclear whether Wal-Mart would have an easier or a harder time penetrating high Herfindahl markets. The results suggest that either there is co- operative behavior in the higher Herfindahl markets or there are higher switching costs in the low Herfindahl markets. Wal-Mart has a harder time penetrating local markets if the incumbent firms are highly focused prior to entry by Wal-Mart into the local market. This result is significant at 6.6%. A ten percent increase in the weighted average focus of the firms in a market leads to a 1.2% decrease in Wal-Mart’s penetration rate. Meyer, Milgrom and Roberts(1992), and Scharfstein and Stein (1997) both argue that firms may sub-optimally finance poorly performing divisions. The implication is that there is more investment in poorly performing divisions and less investment in good performing divisions relative to stand-alone firms. From Chapter 3 it is known that diversified firms are less likely to expand than focused firms. It may also be that they are less likely to initiate price wars or tobeconsistent. 80 influence zoning decisions. The findings here would be more consistent with the predictions for good performing divisions, as it appears that the diversified firms do not fight as hard as the focused firms. However, this does not seem plausible given that many of these firms entered Chapter 11 and/or exited the industry after competing against Wal-Mart. This would imply that future prospects would have been poor for many firms. The results are more consistent with Stein who argues that funding may be restricted to those divisions that are expected to perform poorly relative to other divisions. He argues that this is most relevant for firms that are diversified in related industries. Most of the diversified firms in this industry are diversified retailers and thus are diversified in related areas. The results are also consistent with diversified firms lacking a credible threat to fight, as they have lower opportunity costs. Once firm debt levels, firm focus levels, firm profitability, market Herfindahls have been added to the regression specification, the significance of the managerial ownership variable disappears. From the correlation matrix in Table 26 it can be seen that markets whose stores are owned by firms with higher managerial ownership have stores with lower debt levels, and higher focus than markets whose stores are owned by firms with lower managerial ownership. Since lower debt and higher focus each marginally make Wal-Mart’s 81 penetration more difficult, this appears to be what was driving the ownership results before the additional variables were entered. With respect to Model 1, the Ramsey RESET test cannot reject the null hypothesis that the model has no omitted variables at the 5% level. Multicollinearity does not appear to be too large a problem. The VIF’s for all of the variables other than the annual year dummies are less than three. The highest VIF is 16.0 for one of the annual year dummies. Regional dummies were also put in the model to see if there was any un-modeled market heterogeneity. The United States was divided into six regions, the Northeast, Southeast, West, Foundry, Mid-West, and the Empty region. Five of them were put in the regression, and none of them was significant. An F test was done to test the joint significance of the regional dummies. The null hypothesis that the coefficients are all zero cannot be rejected at the five percent level. Thus, the results with the regional dummies included in the specification are not shown. Local markets that have a high fraction of stores owned by focused firms also tend to have a high fraction of stores owned by profitable firms as these two variables are positively correlated. The model was re-estimated first dropping the profitability measure w ssqj (Model 2), then dropping the focus variable, w fOCj (Model 3). When one of these variables is dropped, the significance of the other is increased. When the profitability measure is dropped, the 82 focus variable becomes significant at less than 1%. When the focus variable is dropped, the profitability variable remains negative but becomes significant at 2%. This implies that Wal-Mart has a harder time penetrating markets with focused firms in them, and these markets tend to have more profitable firms in them. Note that none of the other variables’ coefficients or significance levels change much when either of these variables is dropped. A graph was done plotting the residuals versus the fitted values. There was no curvature or pattern in the residuals. The assumption that the penetration of Wal-Mart is linear in the independent variables appears to be reasonable. The results are basically consistent with the results in Chapter 3 and imply that expanding against Wal-Mart in a local market reduces Wal-Mart’s penetration in that market. In Chapter 3, the findings show that incumbents with higher debt, and higher market shares (higher market Herfindahl’s) are less likely to expand against new entrant, Wal-Mart, in local market j. Wal-Mart gains higher market share in markets that consist of high amounts of firms with these traits. The findings in Chapter 3 show that incumbents with higher focus and higher profits are more likely to expand against new entrant, Wal-Mart, in local market j. Wal-Mart gains lower market share in markets that consist of high amounts of firms with these traits less. However, another result from Chapter 3 was that 83 incumbent firms with high insider ownership or low dependence on a market were less likely to expand against new entrant, Wal-Mart in local market j controlling for the other variables. It is assumed that when Wal-Mart enters a new market that they disturb the equilibrium and a new equilibrium will eventually emerge. It is not clear that the new equilibrium is in place in a local market by the beginning of Year +2. As a robustness check, the results were re-estimated using Wal-Mart’s market share in local market j at the beginning of Year +4. However, a potential problem exists with a longer time window. With a longer window, various factors may change and other variables may determine Wal-Mart’s market share other than the firm and market specific variables measured at the beginning of Year —1. Wal-Mart’s market share is measured by determining the fraction of total stores in local market j at the beginning of Year +4 that are Wal-Marts. The dependent variable will be denoted as “penfivej”. All other variables remain unchanged. All observations where Wal-Mart is first seen competing in a local market at the beginning of 1993 or 1994 now have to be dropped as I only have store location data until the beginning of 1996. This lowers the number of observations from 233 to 176. The model specification to be estimated using OLS is as follows: penfivej,4=a+ B. wfoc,;.1+ B;wdebt,-,.1+ Bawowp,“ + B4Wdcpj..| + Bswssqid + 05 proplgm + [Emodherfjn + B; lustre-,1 + B.annualtime dummies+ s,- 34 Summary statistics are located in Table 29. Table 30 shows the estimation results for three models. OLS estimation was used in all of the models." Annual year dummies were included in all three of the model estimations, but their coefficients are not shown. In all three models the Cook-Weisberg (1983) test rejects the null hypothesis of no homoskedasticity at 5%. Hence, the standard errors used in all three models are White’s heteroskedasticity robust standard errors. Model 1 is the full model where the estimation is run using all of the variables. All of the coefficients have the same sign as they did using the shorter event window except the coefficient on the weighted ownership variable, which is still not significant. The results are stronger for the coefficients on the weighted firm debt variable, the Herfindahl variable, and the weighted firm profitability variable (wssq). The coefficient on the firm focus variable is no longer significant, but on inspection, the correlation of this variable with weighted firm profitability is higher in this smaller sample. Due to the correlation between these two variables, the model was re- estimated first dropping the profitability measure w 83% (Model 2), then dropping the focus variable, w fOCj (Model 3). When one of these variables is dropped, the significance of the other is "SincethedepmdmtvariableisbormdedbetwemwomdmeaTobitestimationprocedmemightbe approprime. I-Ioweva,observationsateithcrexu‘emearerare,soOLSestimationisusedasitisbelievedto 85 increased. When the profitability measure is dropped, the focus variable becomes significant at less than 1%. When the focus variable is dropped, the profitability variable remains negative but becomes significant at less than 1%. This implies that Wal-Mart has a harder time penetrating markets with focused firms in them, and these markets tend to have more profitable firms in them. Note that as before, none of the other variables’ coefficients or significance levels change much when either of these variables is dropped. It would be reasonable to conclude that widening the event window from three to five years made the results slightly stronger. It appears that a new equilibrium was relatively established after the three-year period. If one assumes that the equilibrium number of stores is static, then a third possible dependent variable would be to determine what fraction of the stores in a market at the beginning of Year —1 are owned by Wal-Mart at the beginning of Year +2. As a robustness check, the results were re-estimatcd using the number of stores that Wal-Mart has in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 divided by the total number of stores in local market j at the beginning of Year —1. This dependent variable will be denoted as “penbasej”. All other variables remain unchanged. The model specification to be estimated using OLS is as follows: be consistent. 86 penbase5=a+fll Wfocikl + B:wdebt,-,1+ B3W0WPj.-i +54Wd€pj,-i + BsWSSqi-i + [36 P1013183}: + B7modhert},. + B; lnstrs,-,.1+ Biannualtime dummies+aj The summary statistics are the same as those shown in Table 27, as these are the same observations used in the first specification. Only the dependent variable has changed. Table 31 shows the estimation results for three models. OLS estimation was used in all ofthe models. Annual year dummies were included in all three of the model estimations, but their coefficients are not shown. The standard errors used in all three models are White’s heteroskedasticity robust standard errors. Model 1 shows the results using all ofthe variables. The results are similar to earlier results. Wal-Mart gains a higher fraction of the number of stores that existed at the beginning of Year —1 by the beginning of Year +2 in local markets that have higher Herfindahls and that have firms with higher debt. As before, having focused firms in a market increases the “toughness” of a market as Wal-Mart gains a lower fraction of the number of stores that existed in the beginning of Year -1 in local markets that have highly focused firms in them. In this case the dependent variable does not adjust for increases in the number of stores by any other firms in the event window. It assumes that a local market is in equilibrium and will stay the same size. It makes sense that Wal- Mart would want to add more stores to markets that have firms that 87 are more profitable with this dependent variable. It may be that these firms are more profitable because they are in markets that are under-stored. The competitors may also be expanding in these markets. The other dependent variables, pen,- and penfivej automatically adjust for this possibility. In Models 2 & 3, where weighted sales per square foot and weighted firm focus are each dropped, only market herfindahls and market size remain significant. 4.4.4 Incumbent Penetration: Markets With Both Public and Private Firms In Section 4.4.1, tests showed that Wal-Mart had a harder time gaining market share in local markets the higher the proportion of stores in the market owned by private firms. When looking at local markets consisting of only public firms, Wal-Mart had a harder time gaining market share in local markets that had firms with higher weighted managerial ownership. These results held even after controlling for local market size and firm size. In Section 4.4.3, the results using local markets with only public firms were examined more closely to determine why Wal-Mart had a difficult time gaining market share in the markets consisting of stores with high levels of firm managerial ownership. In this section all local 88 markets are examined, including those with private firms, to see if private firms act similarly to high ownership public firms. The specifications run on markets with stores owned by only public firms, are re-estimatcd using all markets and making some variable changes. As in the earlier tests done in Sections 4.4.1, the fraction of private firms in the local market is used to see if having extreme measures of managerial ownership is important. The information needed to create the focus variable was not available for all of the private firms, and thus this variable was not used in the first tests to be shown below. Debt ratios are not available for private firms, but a LBO dummy variable is used if a market has at least one store in it at the beginning of Year -1 that is owned by a firm that has recently done a LBO. This variable is defined as follows: LBO dummy]: Equals 1 if local marketj has at least one stores owned by a firm that has done a LBO in the three years prior to the beginning of Year —1; Otherwise = 0. All other variables are the same as were used in earlier specifications. The models to be estimated are as follows and differ only with respect to the dependent variable: 89 Model 1: Penj.+2 = a. + 131130 dummyi + 52 W 134 + 153 W delta-1 + 34 W 53% + 35 1910131ng + 56 find heft} + 57 “Susi-I +B.annualtimedummies+sj Model 2: Penfivej,“ = a + BILBO dummyj + Bzfi‘acprim + B;wdep,-,.1+ [34 w ssq; + 135 Pmplgj.-1 + 136 End herfi + 137 lnstrsiq + 8. annual time dummies + e,- Model3: Penbasej=a+ BlLBOdUIDij +Bzfi’acprij,.1+B3wdep,-,.i +B4wssqi +BstP18i-1 + 56 1110411611} + B71nStTSj.-l +Btannualtimedummies+ej A potential problem exists when including markets with privately held firms in the sample. The debt ratios for the privately held firms are not available. Also, the focus variable is not available for all private firms. This could least to biased estimates of the remaining coefficients. Table 32 shows the simple correlation matrix using the observations for all local markets. These relationships between variables can be compared to those using local markets consisting of stores owned by only public firms in Table 26. The correlations between markets with a high fraction of stores owned by private firms in them and other variables are very similar to the correlations between markets with stores owned by firms with high managerial ownership and those variables. Local markets with a high fraction of stores owned by private firms tended to be low Herfindahl markets, have less profitable firms in them, and have smaller firms 90 in them. However, the correlations with profitability and Herfindahl are close to zero. The markets with stores owned by public firms only, with high managerial ownership, tended to have smaller firms in them, have less profitable firms in them, be in low Herfindahl markets, have more focused firms in them, and have firms with lower debt in them. E” The summary statistics are shown in Table 33. Table 34 shows the estimation results using the three different dependent variables. OLS estimation was used in all of the models. Annual 5 year dummies were included in all three of the model estimations, but their coefficients are not shown. The standard errors used in all three models are White’s heteroskedasticity robust standard errors. In all three models, the fraction of private firms in the market is negative and significant at 1.4%, less than 1% and at 6.6%. This implies that Wal-Mart has a harder time penetrating markets with a high fraction of private firms in them. Modified Herfindahl is still positive and significant at less than 1%, and the size of the market, lnstrsj, i is still negative and significant at less than 1%. The LBO dummy is not significant in any of the specifications. The specifications can be run adding the focus variable. Six local markets have to be dropped due to a lack of information regarding the focus variable for at least one firm in the local market. 91 Modell: Peni+2=a+ Bifi'acprii-I+Bzwf0¢i+fisWd¢Pi4+l54WSSqi +BsPr°P18m + Bomodhert} + B7m-I + Biannual time dummies + 8]- Mode12: Pem+2=a+Biwowm.i + Bzwfoci4+ B3Wdepi-1+B4WSSQj,-l +135 Proplai-l +Bsm0dherfi.-1+Bilnstrsi-i + B, annualtirne dummies+ c,- The results are shown in Table 35. In both specifications, the managerial ownership variable is negative and~significant at less than 1%. This implies that Wal-Mart has a harder time penetrating markets with a high fraction of stores owned by private firms, and a harder time penetrating markets with only public firm owned stores in them when the firms owning the stores have high managerial ownership. This again supports that private firms are apparently taking similar actions, and Wal-Mart finds these actions to be “tougher”. In both specifications Wal-Mart has a tougher time gaining market share in markets that have more profitable firms in them. When the debt variable is omitted, the focus variable becomes positive and significant. In the earlier specification when debt was included for the public only markets, focus was negative and significant. The switch in the sign on the focus variable is probably due to an omitted variable bias. Given that the public and private market coefficients are very similar to those for public firms only, it again appears that private firms are taking actions similar to high managerial ownership public firms. 92 4.4.5 Herfindahls and Profitability Earlier results showed that Wal-Mart gained higher penetration in high Herfindahl markets then in low Herfindahl markets. It was unclear whether this was due to more co-operative behavior on the part of the incumbents in the high Herfindahl markets or if it was due to higher switching costs in the low Herfindahl markets. It would be beneficial to empirically test to see if high Herfindahl markets had high profits. If they do, this would support co-operative behavior in these markets. It would also be instructive to see what happens to market Herfindahls and market profits when Wal-Mart enters a local market. The correlation matrices show a positive simple correlation coefficient between market Herfindahl’s and the profitability of the firms that are in the high Herfindahl markets (see Tables 26 & 32). The problem with this is that the Herfindahl is based on only the local market j, while the firm profitability is based on the firm—wide profits ofthe firms who have stores in local market j and is not the firm profits in market j alone. Unfortunately, profits at the 3-digit zip code level are unavailable, The empirical results shown earlier demonstrate that Wal-Mart ends up with a higher market share in the markets that have high Herfindahls. This provides some evidence of profit potential in these markets and cooperation. If Wal-Mart had a lower market share in high Herfindahl markets after a few years of 93 competing in those markets, this would provide some evidence that the incumbents in these markets had effective mechanisms to block entry and expansion. Discount Merchandiser, a trade journal for the discount department store industry, reports sales per square footage of selling space for standard discount department stores for every State, for every year during the sample period. I calculated Herfindahl’s for every local market for the earlier tests that were reported. The arithmetic average of the Herfindahls for all of the local markets within each State was then calculated. The ending result was the creation of the average local market Herfindahl for each State for each year. With a measure of profitability per State and a measure of market concentration per State for each year, tests can be done to see if higher Herfindahl markets have higher profits. The variables of interest are defined as follows: herfnz The arithmetic average of the local market (3-digit zip code) modified Herfindahls as defined in section 4.4.2 for every 3-digit zip code in State i for year t. infssqm The sales per square footage of selling space for standard discount department stores for every State i, for every year t as reported in Dieeeunr Merchandiser. 94 propwalm The number of Wal-Marts as a fraction of the total number of stores in State i during year t. (Stated in percentage form.) propwal" sqd : This is propwali, raised to the second power. Table 36 shows summary statistics for these variables. The data consists of observations on all fifty states for 1980 — 1995. The first specification tests to see if States with higher average local market Herfindahls have higher profits. The model to be estimated by pooled OLS is: infssqg=a+filherfh +B,annualyeardummies+eh The results are shown in Table 37. Annual year dummies were put in the specification to control for any aggregate time effects. The results show that States with higher average local market Herfindahls have higher profits (inflation adjusted sales per square foot). The second specification tests to see if the proportion of Wal- Marts in a State determines the average herfindahl for the State. The proportion of Wal-Mart’s in the state squared is also included 95 to control for any non-linearities. The model to be estimated by pooled OLS is: herfa=a+Bipropwalh +szropwala. sqd+Bgannualyeardummies+au The results are shown in column two of Table 37 and imply a u shaped effect on Herfindahl. The Herfindahl measure falls when the proportion of Wal-Marts in a State increases but then rises. The third specification tests to see if the proportion of Wal- Marts in a State determines the profitability levels in the State. The proportion of Wal-Mart’s in the state squared is also included to control for any non-linearities. The results imply a u shaped effect on profitability within the State. The profitability in the State first falls when the proportion of Wal-Marts in a State increases but then rises. 4.5 Summary This chapter explored the relationship between firm and market specific characteristics and Wal-Mart’s ability to gain market share. The findings suggest Wal-Mart had a difficult time gaining market share in markets with a high proportion of high ownership firms. This result holds even after controlling for firm and market size and whether the high ownership firms are publicly 96 or privately held. There does not appear to be any support for the entrenchment hypothesis, but this is not surprising given that this is a competitive industry with low barriers to entry. The results also support predatory behavior on Wal-Mart’s part when entering markets whose stores are owned by firms with high amounts of debt. Interestingly, Wal-Mart also has an easier time penetrating markets whose stores are owned by diversified firms. There is also some evidence that Wal-Mart has a tougher time gaining market share in local markets whose stores belong to firms that are more profitable. Another finding is that Wal-Mart gains higher market share in more highly concentrated markets. Evidence is presented that these markets are more profitable as well. CHAPTERS Summary In this dissertation I extend existing research in the product :- market literature area by studying how managerial ownership as well as other firm and market specific characteristics affect firm aggressiveness in the product market. Very little empirical work *- has been done to test varying firm specific determinants of product market interactions. I find that several firm and market specific characteristics do determine investment decisions on the part of incumbent firms when they face a new competitive threat. I find that private firms are less likely to expand then public firms. I also find that public firms with high managerial ownership are less likely to expand then public firms with low managerial ownership. I present evidence suggesting the results are due to differences in managerial ownership and not differences in access to capital, or organizational form. Other results that emerge are that a higher level of debt decreases the likelihood of expansion, a higher level of focus increases the likelihood of expansion, and the more dependent a firm is on the market under attack, the greater the likelihood of expansion. 97 98 I also find that several firm and market specific characteristics determine Wal-Mart’s ability to gain market share. Wal-Mart has a more difficult time gaining market share in local markets whose stores are owned by firms with high managerial ownership. This result holds even after controlling for firm and market size. This provides support for agency theory. The implication here is that managerial incentives and/or monitoring cannot totally mitigate agency problems. A spline function was also estimated to test for the entrenchment hypothesis, but no evidence supporting it was found. Other results are that the new entrant, Wal-Mart, does prey on firms with high debt levels. Firms that are focused as well as the more profitable firms also tend to deter Wal-Mart’s penetration into their markets. Higher Herfidahl markets are more profitable, and Wal-Mart gains higher market share in these markets. This provides support for cooperative behavior occurring in these markets. APPENDICES APPENDIX A APPENDIX A- TABLES Table l Chains Attacked by Wal-Mart Thechainnamesareshownbelow. Ifmorethanonefirmownedachaindm-ingthc periodflnnthcfirmnameisshowninparentheses. Ames Anderson’s Bargain Town USA (Bargain Town) Bargain Town USA (Kinder-Care) Bradlees Caldor Clover Cook United Danners Duckwall-Alco Gold Circle & Richway Fishers Big Wheel Fred Meyer Gambles (Gamble-Skogmo) Gambles (Wickes) Gaylords Gee Bee GI Joe Giantway Grandpa’s Harts (Big Bear Inc) Harts (Penn Trafiic) Hecks Hills Howard Brothers Jacks Jamesway Jefl‘erson Ward Kings Kmart Kuhns Lechmere Magic Mart Maloneys Marshalls Maxway Meijer Murphy G.C. Pamida Prangeway Quality Rich’s Roses Schottenstein SE Nichols Shopko Sky City Stein Mart Stuarts Swallens Target TG&Y Treasury Van Leunens Variety W. Venture Whitney Woolco Zayre 100 Table 2 Summary Statistics: Public and Private Incumbent F inns. Summarystatisticsfor15066rmimarketjpairswhereWa1-Martwasfirstseencompetingina 3-digitzipcodennrketjbetween1976-1994,andinwhichfirmiwasalreadyanincumbem. 59 firmsarerepresentedinthesample. Englanatgry Variables Mean Minimum Maximum Std Dev Private/Public Dummy i .1315 0 1.0 .3380 1 = private 0 = public LBO/No LBO Dummy: .0126 0 1.0 .1116 1 = LBO 0 = No LBO Chain Size 3 636.4655 4 1811 693.8854 Inflation Adjusted Sales 60.5824 15.0816 204.7293 20.3759 per Square Foot i Market Share of FirmI in .2925 .0256 1.0 .1960 Marketj Modified Herfindahl Index .3399 .1224 1.0 .1592 1 Dependence of Firm i on .0164 .0006 .3333 .0323 Market 1 Strength of Wal-Mart .71 18 0 1 .0 .4531 Dummy: 1=1986-1994 0 =1976- 1985 Avg. Indusu'y Growth in .0227 .0062 .0469 .0098 Square Feet 101 Table 3 Simple Correlation Matrix: All Observations Public and Private Using 1506firmi,marketjpairswhereWal-Martwasfirstseencompetingina3-digitzipcode marketjbetween1976-1994,andinwhichfirmiwasalrendyanincumbent. 59firmsare representedinthesample. Pri/LBO/ChainS/SqutMod.Depi,-Decadelnd. Pllb NO 82" F15 Shrg Herf Dum. GTOWth Dum LBO Index,- Dums Pri/ Pub 1.00 Duma LBO/ No .220 1.00 LBO Dumi Chain -.322 -.086 1.00 82,- S/Sq -.021 -.137 .356 1.00 Fig Mk1 -.131 -.037 .351 .058 1.00 Shrfi Mod. 1.00 Herf. -.116 -.005 .225 .060 .765 Indeg ' Depfi .508 .006 -.373 -.046 -.095 -.162 1.00 Decade .096 .072 .094 .048 -.017 -.038 .004 1.00 Dum. Ind. -.114 -.092 .024 .007 .110 .124 -.054 .082 1.00 Growth 102 Table 4 Univariate Probit: Public and Private Incumbent Firms Maxinmmlikelihoodestimationresults. Thedependentvariableyij=liffirmieverexpands duringYears—lto+2,otherwiseyg=0. Thereare1506firmimarketjobservatiom. Expansion occurredin219 observations. 59firmsarereprescntedinthe sample. Thevaluesinparentheses amp-values. Marginalcffectsarecalculatedatthemeamofthex’s. Inthecaseofdummy var'mbles,themarginalefi'ectsforthediscretechangeofthedummyfiom0to1isshownbelow theclassicmarginalefi‘ectvalue. Explanatory Model 1 Marg. Effects Model 2 Marg. Effects Variables Coefficients dprob[y=1]/dx Coefficients Dprob[y=1]ld x Constant -1.4148 W” - 0.3131 -1.4315 ""” -0.3176 (0.000) (0.000) Private/Public Dummy: - 0.4385 ‘” -0.0970 -0.4297 “W -0.0953 1: private 0 = public (0.009) -0.0807 (0.0097) -0.0800 LBO/No LBO Dummy; 0.7169 ” 0.1586 0.7198 ” 0.1597 1 = LBO o = No LBO (0.042) 0.2160 (0.041) 0.2176 Chain Size; 0.00012“ 0.00003 0.00008 0.00002 (0.087) (0.2137) Inflation Adjusted Sales 0.0048 ” 0.0011 0.0050 ” 0.0011 Per Square F cot. (0.024) (0.017) Market Share of Firm i in -0.4230 ‘ - 0.0936 Market j (0.069) Modified Herfindahl -0.2182 -0.0484 Index,- (.4182) Dependence of Firm i on 3.6565 ” 0.8091 3.3618 ” 0.7460 Market j 40.01 1) (0.0195) Wal-Mart Strength -0.2440 ‘” - 0.0540 -0.2407 ”’ -0.0534 Dummy (0.005) - 0.0570 (0.006) -0.0563 1 8 ‘86-’94 0 = ‘76-‘85 Industry Growth in Sq. Ft -8.4801 ‘ -1.8765 -8.9678 ” -1.9899 (0.0505) (0.038) Significance Level 0.00008 0.00025 (HO: B =01 Pseudo R-squared .317 .315 N 1506 1506 Statistically significant at 10% ‘, at 5% "', at 1% ”* A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all ofthe right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 95% level for the specification using market share. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 97. 5% level for the specification using modified herfindahl. The specifications were re-run using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p- values are virtually identical to those shown above for both specifications. Pseudo R-Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (1975). 103 Table 5 Univariate Probit: Public and Private Incumbent Firms Time Dummies Inchided Maximum likelihood estimtion results. The dependent variable Yij=1 iffirm i ever expands duringYears-l to+2; MCYfij = 0. Thereare1506 firmimarketj observations. Expansion occurred in 219 observations. 59 firms are represented in the sample. The values in parentheses are p-values. Marginal effects are calculated at the mean of the x’s. In the case of dummy variables, the nmrginal effects for the discrete change of the dummy fiom 0 to 1 is shown below the classic marginal efl‘ects value. The sample was broken into 8 two-year periods and 1 three- year period. 8 time dummies were included in the specification, but the coefficients are not F shown below. Explanatory Variables Coefficients Marginal Coefficients Effects Robust p-values dprob1y=llldx (White’s) Constant - 1.8029 ”" - 0.3871 - 1.8029 ”" L- (0.006) (0.005) Private/Public Dummy; - 0.4332 ” -0.0930 - 0.4332 ”" 1: private 0 = public (0.011) ~0.0772 (0.009) LBO/No LBO Dummy; 0.5702 0.1224 0.5702 1 = LBO o = No LBO (0.113) 0.1598 (0.105) Chain Size; 0.00013 " 0.00003 0.00013 " (0.082) (0.073) Inflation Adjusted Sales 0.0060 ”" 0.0013 0.0060 ”* Per Square F cot; (0.007) (0.004) Market Share of Firm i in - 0.5089 " - 0.1093 - 0.5089 "' Market j (0.034) (0.040) Dependence of Firm i on 3.7834 ”* 0.8123 3.7834 ‘"“ Market j (0.009) (0.005) Wal-Mart Strength Dummy - 0.2311 - 0.0496 - 0.2311 1 = 1986-1994 (0.317) - 0.0524 (0.317) 0 = 1976-1985 Industry Growth in Sq. Ft - 1.7699 -0.3800 - 1.7699 (0.900L (0.897) Significance Level 0.00000 0.00000 (Ho: 5 =01 Pseudo R-squared .336 N 1506 Statistically significant at the 10% *, at 5% “, at 1% ”W A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 99% level. None of the 8 time dummies is significant. The specification was re- nm using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p-values are shown above. Pseudo R- Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (1975). 104 Table 6 Summary StatisticszPrivateIncumbentFirm. Summarystatisticsfor l98firminnrketjpairswhereWal—Martwasfirstseencompetingina3- digitzipcodemarketjbetween1976-l994,andinwhichfirmiwasalreadyanincumbent. 24 firmsarerepresentedinthesample. Explanatory Variables Mean Min. Max. Sthev. LBO/No LBO Dummy .0758 0 1.0 .2653 1 = LBO 0 = No LBO Chain Size 62.19 4 162 49.79 Inflation Adjusted Discount 59.50 19.98 204.73 34.08 Sales per Square Foot Market Slme of Firm i in .2265 .0476 1.0 .1800 Market j Dependence of Firm i on .0585 .0062 .3333 .0642 Market j Strength of Wal—Mart Dummy .8232 0 1.0 .3824 l =1986-1994 0= 1976-1985 Avg. Industry Growth in .0198 .0062 .0376 .0085 Square Feet 105 Table 7 Univariate Probit: Private Incumbent Firms Maximum likelihood estinntion results. The dependent variable Yij = 1 if firm i ever expands duringYears-l to+2; otherwiseyg=0. Thereare 198 firmimarketj observations. Expamion occurred in 21 observations. 24 firm are represented in the sample. The values in parentheses are p-values. Marginal effects are calculated at the means of the x’s. In the case of dummy variables,themarginalefl'ects forthediscretechange ofthedummy fiomOto 1 isshownbelow the classic marginal efl‘ects value. r- Explamtory Variables Coemcients Margiml Efl‘ects dProb[y=1]/dx Constant -l.8529 "" -0.3034 (0.001) LBO/No LBO Dummyi 0.8290 " 0.1358 1 = LBO 0 = No LBO (0.057) 0.2038 7 Chain Size; 0.0031 0.0005 (0.390) Inflation Adjusted Sales 0.0076 ” 0.0012 Per Square Footi (0.03 3) Market Share of Firm i in Market -0.3192 -0.0523 j (0.725) Dependence of Firm i on Market j 3.5922 0.5883 (0.1024) Decade Dummy -0.3921 -0.0642 1 = 1986-1994 0 = 1976-1985 (0.231) -0.0757 Industry Growth in Sq. Ft. -0.0589 -0.0096 (0.997) Significance Level (Ho: [3 =0) 0.1607 Pseudo R-squared .3176 N 198 Statistically significant at 10% ‘, at 5% ”, at 1% "W A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 95% level. The specification was re-run using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p-values are virtually identical to those shown above except for inflation adjusted sales per square foot which has a p-value of.018 and the dependence offirm i on marketj which has a p-value of .053. Pseudo R-Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (197 5). 106 Table 8 Summary Stat'mtics: Public Incumbent Firms Summary statistics for 1209firmi, marketjpairswhere Wal-Martwasfirstseencompetingina 3-digitzipcodemarketj between 1976- l994,andinwhichfirmiwasalreadyanincumbem. 38 public firms are represented in the sample. Explanatory Variables Mean Min. Max. Std. Dev. % Insider Ownershij i 0.1056 0.0009 .7548 0.1763 Total Debt to Assets ; 0.6445 .2894 1.1530 0.1537 Focus ; 0.7360 .0077 1.0 0.3090 Chain Size i 765.65 19 1811 715.81 Inflation Adjusted Sales per Sq. 62.18 15.08 110.55 17.06 Ft. i Operating Profit Margin 5 (11111929 .0649 -.0598 .5247 .0753 ‘Operating Profit Margim am a!) .0535 -.0598 .1740 .0266 Market Slmre of Firm i in Mkt j 0.2988 .0256 1.0 0.1934 Dependence on Market j 0.0099 .0006 .1739 0.0167 Strength of Wal-Mart Dummy 0.7378 0 1.0 0.4400 1 = 1986—1994 0 = 1976—1985 Avg. Industry Growth in Square 0.0228 .0062 .0376 0.0097 Feet ’NOTE: Onefirmhadanoperatingprofitmarginthatwasmuchlargerthanthatoftheother firmsinthesample. Itwasdroppedinthespecificationthatusesoperatingprofitmargin. 107 Table 9 Simple Correlation Matrix: Public Firm Observations Using 1209 firmi, marketjpairswhereWal-Martwasfirstseencompeting ina3-digit zipcodemarketjbetween1976-1994,andinwhichfirmiwasah'eadyanincumbent. 38firmsarerepresentedinthesample. % Debt ChainS/Sq Mkt.Dep DecadeInd Focus fl. Mgr to Size Shr J Dum Growth Assets %Mgr 1.00 pr Debtto -.048 1.00 Assets Chain -.412 -.083 1.00 Size S/Sq. -.297 -.159 .426 1.00 Ft. Mkt. -.102 .038 .390 .123 1.00 Shr. DQJ .328 -.032 -.454 -.264 -.070 1.00 Decade -.146 .214 .081 .080 .020 -.054 1.00 Ind. .006 .231 .005 -.006 .045 -.021 .126 1.00 Focus .247 .234 .358 .077 .212 -.237 -.049 .061 1.00 108 Table 10 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbent Firms Maximmlikelihoodestimationresults.Thedependentvariableyfi=liffirmieverexpands duringYears-lto+2;otherwiseyg=0. Thespecification ha31209firmimktjobservatiom. Expansion occurred in 173 obs. 38 firms are represented in the sample. The values in parenthesesarep-values. Marginaleffectsarecalculatedatfliemeamofthex’slnthecaseof dummy variables, the marginal effects for the discrete clunge of the dummy fiom 0 to 1 is shown belowtheclassicmargimlefi‘ectsvalue. Explanatory Variables Coefiicients Marg. Efl‘ects dProb[y=l]/dx Constant -0.7896 ” -0.1684 (0.015) % Insider Ownership, -1.2025 ”" -0.2565 (0.002) Total Debt to Assets; -1.1979 "W -0.2555 (0.002) Focusi 0.5493 “‘ 0.1172 (0.0099) Clnin Size; 0.000005 0.000001 (0.962) Inflation Adjusted Sales Per 0.0065 ” 0.0014 Square Ft, (0.031) Market Share of Firm i in -0.4319 -0.0921 Market 1 (0.104) Dependence of Firm i on 10.135‘" 2.1620 Market j (0.0004) Wal-Mart Strength Dummy —0.0529 -0.0113 1 = ‘86-’94 0 = ‘76-‘85 (0.614) -0.1145 Industry Growth in Sq. Ft - 7.6560 -1.6331 (0.121) Significance Level 0.000002 (HO: 13 =0) Pseudo R-squared .334 N 1209 Statistically significant at 10% a, at 5% n, at 1% m LM test statisties were done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 95% level. The specification was re-run using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p-values are virtually identical to those shown above and are not shown. Pseudo R-Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (1975). 109 Table 11 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbent Firms The Dummies Included Maximum likelihood estimation results. The dependent variable y;,- = 1 if firm i ever expands dmingYears-lto+2;otherwiseyg=0. Thereare1209firmimktj observations. Expansion occturedin173obs.and38firmsarerepresentedinthesample. Thevaluesinparenthesesarep- values. Marginal effects are calculated at the means of the x’s. In the case of dummy variables, themarginaleffectsforthediscretechangeofthedummyfiomOtolisshownbelowtheclassic marginal effects value. The sample was broken into 8 two-year pciods and 1 three-year period 8 time rhunmies were inchtded in the specification, but the coeflicients are not shown below. H Explanatory Variables Coefficients Marg. Efl‘ects Coefl’icients dProb[y=1]/dx Robust p-values (White’s) Constant -0.6778 -0.1405 -0.6778 (0.384) (0.363) t % Insider Ownership, -l.3l76 “‘ -0.2731 -1.3176 "M (0.001) (0.001) Total Debt to Assets, -1.1548 "” -0.2394 -1.1548 ’” (9.004) (0.007) Focus. 0.5522 ” 0.1145 0.5522 ”‘ (0.013) (0.007) Chain Size. 0.00003 0.000006 0.00003 (0.785) (0.762) Inflation Adjusted 0.0058 " 0.0012 0.0058 ” Sales Per Square Ft, (0.069) (0.039) Market Share of Firm i -0.5270 " -0.1092 -0.5270 " in Market j (0.053) (0.063) Dependence of Firm i 9.820 ”“ 2.0355 9.820 ‘” on Market j (0.0008) (0.000) Wal-Mart Strength -0.2785 -0.0577 -0.2785 Dummy (0.260) (0.269) 1 = ‘86-’94 0 = ‘76-‘85 Industry Growth in Sq. -2.8889 -0.5988 -2.8889 Ft (0.867) (0.857) Significance Level 0.00000 (Ho: B =01 Pseudo R-squared .3512 1209 N Statistically significant at 10% ’, at 5% ”, at 1% "" LM test statistics were done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity can be rejected at the 99.5% level. The specifications were re-nm using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p-values are shown above. None of the 8 time dummies is significant in either of the regressions. Pseudo R-Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (1975). 110 Table 12 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbent Firms Using Operating Profit Margin Maximum likelihood estinmtion results. The dependent variable ya = 1 if firm i ever expands during Years -1 to +2; otherwise y“ = 0. The specification has 1178 firm i mkt j observatiom. Expansion occlu'red in 168 obs. and 37 firms are represented in the sample. (One firm was dropped as its opm was a large outlier.) The values in parentheses are p-values. Marginal effects are calculated at the means of the x’s. In the case of dummy variables, the marginal effects for the discrete change of the dummy from 0 to 1 is shown below the classic margiml efl'ects value. Explanatory Coefficients Marg. Efl‘ects Variables dprobjy=1]/dx Constant -0.5841 ’ -0.1228 (0.0556) % Insider -1.3937 ‘” -0.2930 Ownership; (0.0005) Total Debt to Assets, -1 .71 12 "" -0.3598 (0.00008) Focus; 0.8572 *" 0.1802 (0.0003) Chain Size; 0.00002 0.000005 (0.8736) Operating Profit 3.444 * 0.7241 Margim (0.0949) Market Share of -0.5210 " -0.1095 Firm i in Market j (0.0577) Dependence of Firm 10.5099 ”" 2.2096 i on Market 1 (0.0003 Wal-Mart Strength 0.0898 0.0189 Dummy (0.419) 0.1842 1 = ‘86-’94 0 = ‘76- ‘85 Industry Growth in - 7.0078 -1.4733 Sq. Ft (9.156) Significance Level 0.00000 (Ho: B =0) Pseudo R-squared .3422 N 1178 Statistically significant at 10% *, at 5% n, at 1% m A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 95% level. The specification was re-run using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p-values are virtually identical to those shown above and are not shown. Pseudo R-Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (1975). 111 Table 13 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbent Firms Parent Size Added Maximum likelihood estimation results for expansion at the 3-digit zip code level for public incumbents. The dependent variable Yij = l iffirm i ever expands during Years —1 to +2; otherwise yg = 0. There are 1209 firm i mktj observations. Expansion occurred in 173 obs. The values in parentheses are p-values. 38 public firms are represented in the sample. Marginal effects are calculated at the means of the X’s. Explanatory Variables Coeflicients Marginal Effects dprob[y=1]/dx @t mean of X) Constant -0.7799 ‘"" -0.1664 (0.016) % Insider Ownership -l.1989 *" -0.2558 (0.002) Total Debt to Assets -1.l684 ”" -0.2493 (0.003) Focus 0.4819 " 0.1028 (0.043) Clnin Size -0.00009 -0.00002 (0.600) Inflation Adjusted Discount 0.0066 ” 0.0014 Sales Per Square Foot (0.028) Market Share of Firm i in -0.4344 -0.0927 Market 1 (0.102) Dependence of Firm i on Market 10.085 ‘” 2.1517 j (0.0004) Wal-Mart Strength Dummy «0.0486 -0.0104 1 = 1986-1994 0 = 1976-1985 (0.645) Industry Growth in Sq. Ft -6.8498 -1.4614 (0.180) Inflation Adjusted Parent Total -0.00003 -0.000006 Assets (.552) Significance Level .000005 Gio=£=0) Pseudo R-squared .3335 N 1209 Statistically significant at 10% t, at 5% u, .t 1% m A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand Side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 95% level. 112 Table 14 Univariate Probit: Public and Private Incumbents Regional Dummies Maximum likelihood estimation results for expansion at the 3-digit zip code level for private and public incumbents. Thedependentvariableyg= l iffirmiever expands dlu'ingYears—l to+2, otherwise yij = 0. There are 1506 firm i mktj observations. Expamion occurred in 219 observations. The values in parentheses are p-values. Observations were divided into 6 geographic regions and 5 regional dummies were used. The coefficients on the regional dummies are not shown. Marginal effects are calculated at the mean ofthe x’s. In the case ofdummy variables, the marginal effects for the discrete change of the dummy fiom 0 to 1 is shown below the classic marginal efl’ects value. ExplanatoryVariables Coefficients Marg. Effects Coeflicients dprob[y=1]/dx Robust p-values (White’s) Constant -1.5743 "* -0.3388 -1.5743 "”” (0.000) (0.000) Public/Private Dummy - 0.3927 ” - 0.0845 - 0.3927 " 1= private 0 = public (0.024) - 0.0715 (0.025) LBO/No LBO Dummy 1.0223 ” 0.2200 1.0223 " 1 = LBO 0 = No LBO (0.012) 0.3297 (0.011) Chain Size 0.0001 " 0.00003 0.0001 "' (0.085) (0.069 Inflation Adjusted Discount 0.0051 “ 0.0011 0.0051 ” Sales Per Square Foot (0.023) (0.025) Market Share of Firm i in -0.5729 ” -0. 1233 -0.5729 " Market j (0.024) (0.022) Dependence of Firm i on 3.3741 ” 0.7260 3.3741 " Marketj (0.021) (0.012) Wal-Mart Strength Dummy -0.1912 " -0.0412 -0.l912 * 1 = 1986-1994 0 - 1976-1985 (0,059) -0.0430 (0.057) Industry Growth in Sq. Ft -8.2697 "' -1.7794 -8.2697 " (0.070) (0.061) Significance Level 0.0000 THO: [5 =0) Pseudo R-squared .3373 N 1506 Statistically Significant at 10% ’, at 5% ", at 1% *" A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the comtant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 99.5% level. The specification was re-run using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p-values are shown above. One regional dummy is significant at the 1% level. Another regional dummy is significant at the 10% level. 113 Table 15 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbents Regional Dummies Maximum likelihood estimation results. The dependent variable yij = 1 if firm i ever expands dining Years—l to+2; otherwiseyg =0. Thereare1209 firmimktj observations. Expansion occurred in 173 obs. The values in parentheses are p-values. 38 public firms are represented in the sample. Marginal effects are calculated at the means of the x’s. In the case of dummy variables, the mginal effects for the discrete change of the dummy from 0 to 1 is shown below the classic marginal effects value. Observations were divided into 6 geographic regions and 5 regional dummies were used. The coefficients on the regional dummies are not shown. Explanatory Variables Coeflicients Marginal Effects dprob[_y=1]/dx (at mean of X) Constant - 1.2094 ’” -0.2496 (0.002) % Imider Ownership. - 1.4680 ‘” -0.3029 (0.0003) Total Debt to Assets, - 1.0684 “‘ -0.2205 (0.007) Focusi 0.6764 ”" 0.1396 (0.002) Chain Size. -0.000008 -0.000002 (0.936) Inflation Adjusted Discount 0.0067 "“" 0.0014 Sales Per Square Foot, (0.040) Market Share of Firm i in - 0.5800 ” -0.1197 Market j (0.048) Dependence of Firm i on 11.3364 ”W 2.3392 Market j (0.0001) Wal-Mart Strength Dummy 0.0170 0.0035 1 = 1986-1994 0 = 1976- (0.886) 0.0035 1985 Industry Growth in Sq. Ft - 7.0386 -l.4524 (0.180) Significance Level .000000 (Ho: [3 =0) Pseudo R-Squared .3541 N 1209 Statistically significant at 10% *, at 5% ", at 1% "W A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 95% level. The specification was re-run using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p-values are virtually identical to those Shown above and are not shown. Pseudo R-Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (1975). One regional dummy and the constant are significant at the 1% level. Another regional dummy is Significant at the 5% level. 114 Table 16 Univariate Probit: Public and Private Incumbents State Population Changes Maximum likelihood estimation results for expansion at the 3—digit zip code level for private and public incumbents. Thedependentvariableyij= l iffirmiever expandsdm'ing Years-1 to+2, otherwise yg = 0. There are 1422 firm i mkt j observations. Expamion occurred in 205 observations. The values in parentheses are p-values. Marginal efl’ects are calculated at the means of the x’s. In the case of dummy variables, the rmrginal effects for the discrete change of the dummy from 0 to 1 is Shown below the classic marginal effects value. Explanatory Variables Coefficients Marginal Effects Coefi‘tcients dprob[y=1]/dx Robust p-values (White’s) Constmt -1.4771 “* -0.3172 -1.4771 *” (0.000) (0.000) Public/Private Dummy, -0.4517 *” -0.0970 -0.4517 ” 1= private 0 = public @0097) -0.0802 (0.012) LBO/No LBO Dummyi 1.0729 *” 0.2304 1.0729 ”* 1 = LBO 0 = No LBO (0.007) 0.3493 (0.008) Chain Sizet 0.0001 0.00002 0.0001 (0.145) (0.140) Inflation Adjusted Discount 0.0027 0.0006 0.0027 Sales Per Square Foot; (0.227) (0.230) Market Share of Firm i in -0.6242 ” -0.l340 -0.6242 ” Marketj (0.015) (0.019) Dependence of Firm i on 4.5467 "* 0.9764 4.5467 *" Market j (0.002) (0.001) Will-Mart Strength Dummy —.2077 " -0.0446 -.2077 " 1 = 1986-1994 0 - 1976-1985 (0,032) -o.o473 (0,035) Industry Growth in Sq. Ft -6.3177 -1.3567 -6.3177 (0.175) (0.172) State Population Changej 0.0006 *” 0.0001 0.0006 *" (0.000) (0.000) Significance Level 0.0000 (Ho: [3 =0) Pswdo R-squared .3313 N 1422 Statistically significant at 10% ‘, at 5% “, at 1% "" A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 99.5% level. The specification was re-nm using White’s robust estimator of variance. The p-values are shown above. 115 Table 17 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbents State Population Changes Maximum likelihood estimation results. The dependent variable yij = 1 if firm i eva' expands dtu'ingYearS-l to+2; otherwiseyg=0. Thereare 1155 firmimktj observations. Expamion occmredin 160 obs. Thevalues inparenthesesarep—values. 38publicfirmsarerepresentedin the sample. Marginal effects are calculated at the means ofthe x’s. Explanatory Variables Coefficients Marginal Coefficients Effects Robust p-values dprobly=ll/dx W68) Comtant -0.9417 ‘" -0.1930 -0.9417 ”" (0.005) @002) % Insider Ownership, -0.8159 ” -0.1672 -0.8159 ” (0.043) (0.045) Total Debt to Assets; -0.9433 ” -0.l933 -0.9433 ” (0.016) (0.025) Focus, 0.4663 " 0.0956 0.4663 ” (0.036) (0.035) Chain Sizet 0.0001 0.0002 0.0001 (0.240) (0.205) Inflation Adjusted Discount 0.0026 0.0005 0.0026 Sales Per Square Foot (0.435) (0.392) Market Share of Firm i in -0.8441 "" 01730 -0.8441 ”" Market j (0.004) (0.008) Dependence of Firm i on 12.9963 "* 2.6636 12.9963 "‘ Market j (0.000) (0.000) Wal-Mart Strength Dummy 0.0445 0.0091 0.0445 1 = ‘86-‘94 0 = ‘76-‘85 (0.700) (0.718) Industry Growth in Sq. Ft -7.4920 -l.5355 -7.4920 (0.152) (0.145) State Population Change; 0.0007 ”" 0.0001 0.0007 ”‘ (0.000) (0.000) Significance Level 0.0000 0: B =0) Pseudo R-Squared .3381 N 1155 Statistically significant at 10% ’, at 5% u, at 1% see A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 99.5% level. The specification was re-run using White’s robust estimator of variance. The robust p-values are shown above. Pseudo R-Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (1975). 116 Table 18 Univariate Probit: Public Incumbents State Popuhtion Clunges Herfindahl Imtead of Market Share Maxirmmlikelihoodestinntionresults. Thedependentvariableyg=1iffirmieverexpands duringYears—lto+2;otherwisey,,=0. Thereare1155firmimktj observatiom. Expansion occurredinl600bs.Thevaluesinparenthesesarep-values. 38publicfirmsarerepresemedin thesample. Marginal efi'ectsarecalculated atthemeansof the x’s. Explanatory Variables Coefi'lcients Marginal Efl‘ects Coefiicients dprob[y=l]ldx Robust p-values Mites) Comtant -0.8400 ” -0.1731 -0.8400 ” (0.013) (0.007) % Imider Ownership, -0.8574 ” -0.1767 -0.8574 ” (0.033) (0.034) Total Debt to Assets, -0.9823 ” -0.2024 -0.9823 ” (0.012) (0.021) Focus, 0.4351 “ 0.0896 0.4351 “ (0.0499) (0.046) Chain Size, 0.00004 0.000009 0.00004 (0.644) (0.621) Inflation Adjusted Discount 0.0030 0.0006 0.0030 Sales Per Square Foot, (0.355) (0.312) Modified Herfindahl j -0.7419 "" -0.1529 -0.7419 “ (0.033) @037) Dependence of Firm i on 11.3573 "" 2.3400 11.3573 *" Market j (0.000) (0.000) Wal-Mart Strength Dummy 0.0376 0.0077 0.0376 1 = ‘86-‘94 0 = ‘76-‘85 (0.744) (0.761) Industry Growth in Sq. Ft -7.1080 -1.4645 -7.1080 (0.174) (0.169) State Population ChangeJ 0.0007 ”"' 0.0001 0.0007 ‘"” (0.000) (0.000) Significance Level 0.0000 (1'10: 13 =0) Pseudo R-squared N 1155 Statistically significant at 10% ’, at 5% ”, at 1% "* A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variabla except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 99.5% level. The specification was re-nm using White’s robust estimator of variance. The robust p-values are Shown above. Pseudo R-Squared was calculated in Limdep using a formula given by Zavoina and McKelvey (1975). 117 Table 19 Univariate Probit: The Importance of Ownership Controlling for Firm Size, and Economic Growth Maximum likelihood estimation results. Model 1 using public firns only. Model 2 uses both publicandprivatefirms. Thedependentvariableyg=1 iffirmieverexpandsduringYears-lto +2; otherwise y,,- = 0. There are 1209 firm i mkt j observations. Expansion occurred in 173 obs. The values in parentheses are p-values. 38 public firms are represented in the sample. Margiml effects are calculated at the means of the x’s. In the case of dummy variables, the marginal efl’ects forthediscretechangeofthedummyfiomOto 1 isshownThesamplewasbrokeninto8two— year periods and 1 three-year period 8 time dummies were included in the Specification, but the coefficients are not shown below. Explanatory Variables Model 1 Model 1 Model 2 Model 2 Coeflicients Marginal Coefficients Marginal Robust Efl‘ects Robust Efl‘ects p-values dprobly=1]/dx p-values dprob[y=1]/dx (White’s) (White’s) Comtant -0.5177 -1.3669 ” (0.408) (0.026) % Insider Ownership, -0.8122 " -0.1741 (0.017) Public/Private Dummy, -0.3082 “ -.0592 l= private 0 = public (0047) Chain Sizel 0.0001” 0.00003 0.0001 ” 0.00003 (0.047) (0.035) Dependence of Firm i on 7.2150 ”" 1.5468 3.4149 ” 0.7459 Market 1 (0.007) (0.013) Industry Growth in Sq. Ft -4.2646 -0.9143 -3.3955 -0.7417 (-0.792) (0.801) Significance Level 0.0000 0.0000 (HO: 13 =0) N 1209 1506 Statistically Significant at 10% ‘, at 5% ”, at 1% ”"' A LM test statistic was done to check for multiplicative heteroskedasticity using all of the right hand side variables except the constant. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity cannot be rejected at the 99.5% level. The Specification was re-run using White’s robust estimator of variance. The robust p-values are Shown above. 118 Table 20 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share as a Frmction of Ownership in a Local Market The dependent variable for Model 1 & Model 3 is the fiaction of total stores owned by Wal-Mart in local marketj at the beginning onear +2 (M). The dependent variable for Models 2 & 4 is the number of stores owned by Wal-Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 as a fiaction of the total number of stores in local market j at the beginning of Year -1 (penbasq). All models are estimated using OLS with t-statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies wee included in the specifications, but their coefficients are not shown. Tobeinthesample, Wal-Marthastobefirstseen inalocal marketbetween 1981 — 1994. Explanatory Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Variables Coefficients Coefficients Coefl’lciems Coeflicients PM Yi‘Penbfisei Yl=P°ni Yl=Penbasq (All Markets) (All Markets) (Public Markets) (Public Markets) constant 0.414 an 1.026 "* 0.559 ”"' 1.059 ”* (7.407) (3.103) (8.377) (7.981) fracpri, - 0.072 I" - 0.165 in (4.105) (-2241) w oij - 0.320 ""' - 0.984 ”‘ (-3.398) (6.733) Numbe Of 471 471 233 233 Obs. R-Squared .149 .158 .166 .225 Statistically significant at 10% r, at 5% n, at 1% m 119 Table 21 Summary Statistics: All Markets Tobeinthesample, Wal-Marthastobefirstseeninalocalnnrketbetween 1981—1994. 471 obs. Explanatory Mean Standard Minimum Maximum Variables Deviation fracprii .1434 .2233 0.0 1.0 w depl- 1.565 % 2.031% .0437°/o 22.577% W .0271 .0951 0.0 1.0 lnstrs;L 1.831 .7939 0 3.784 120 Table 22 Summary Statistics: Markets With All Public Incumbents To be inthe sample, Wal-Martlms to be first seen ina local market between 1981 - 1994. 233 obs. Explanatory Mean Standard Minimum Maximum Variables Deviation w oij .0917 .1033 .0038 .5859 w clep-L .8047 % .8124 % .0437% 6.1587% m .9315 .1519 0 1.0 lnstrsj 1.6003 .8055 0 3.5264 121 Table 23 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Stare as a Function of Ownership in a LocalMarket: Market andFirmSize ControlsAdded ThedependentvariableforModel l &Model3isthefi'actionoftotalstoresownedbyWal-Mart inlocalmarketj atthebeginningonear+2 (penj).ThedependentvariableforMode182&4is the number of stores owned by Wal-Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 as a fi'actionofthetotalnumberofstoresinlocalmarketj atthebeginningonear-l (penbasej). All models are estimted using OLS with t-statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included inthe specificatiom, buttheir coefficients arenot shownTobeinthesample,Wal-Marthastobefirstseeninalocalmarketbetween1981—1994. Explanatory Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Variables Coefficients Coeflicients Coeflicients Coeflicients 1=pens ”=9ch yin-pen: y1=lmbtsq (All Markets) (All Markets) (Public Markets) (Public Markets) comtant 0.630 m 1.387 m 0.642 m 1.113 m (9.277) (4.683) (4.230) (6.179) impri- - 0.079 n - 0.118 n (.2374) (.2498) wow; -0.198 n - .0517 m (.2195) (-2.963) locus,- - 0.122 m - 0.273 m - 0.145 m - 0.282 m (44.594) (12.074) (-9.362) (42.450) proplg - 0.0008 0.130 n 0.054 0.235 '- (-0.014) (2.382) (0.494) (1.923) Wdepj 0.001 0.001 0.047 9* 0.026 (0.439) (0.233) (2.284) (0.244) Number of 471 471 233 233 Obs. R-squared 0.501 .538 .4817 .607 Statistically significant at 10% ‘, at 5% ”, at 1% ”" 122 Table 24 Constrained Least Squares Spline Regressions Testing For Differences in Slope Coefficients for Difl‘erent Ownership Groups: Market and Firm Size Controls Added The dependent variable for Model 1 is the fi'action of total stores owned by Wal-Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 (penj). The dependent variable for Model 2 is the number of stores owned by Wal-Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 as a fraction of the total number of stores in local market j at the beginning of Year —1 (penbasq). All models are estimated using OLS with t-statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included in the specifications, but their coefficients are not shown. To be inthe sample, Wal-Marthasto be first seen in a local market between 1981 —1994. Explamtory Model 1 Model 2 Variables Coefficients Coeflicients Y1: P601 Y1: MM (Public Markets) (Public Markets) Constant 0.648 ”’ 1.166 ”" (4.245) (6.841) w oij - 0.354 - 3.254 "" (-0.515) (-2.775) (11(0ij - .05) 0.135 3.025 “ (0.166) (2.220) (12 (oij - .25) 0.138 0.177 (0.352) (0.267) lnstrsj - 0.144 ”" -0.271 ”t (-9.467) (-12.l62) proplg 0.050 0.221 ‘ (0.439) (1.770) w depj 0.047 " 0.023 (2.278) (0.329) Number of Obs. 233 233 R-squared .186 .617 Statistically significant at 10% t, at 5% n, at 1% m 123 Table 25 OLS Spline Regression: Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share as a Function of Different Ownership Groups: Market and Firm Size Controls Added The dependent variable is the number of stores owned by Wal-Mart in local mrket j at the beginning onear +2asafi-actionofthetotal numberofstores in local marketj atthebeginning of Year —1 (penbasej). The model is estimated using constrained least squares with t-statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included in the specifications, but their coefficients are not shown. To be in the sample, Wal-Mart has to be first seen in a local rmrket between 1981 - 1994. Explanatory Variables Model Coefficients 10 = penbasei (Public Markets) Constant 1.166 ”" (6.841) w own-,1 0 to .05 -3.254 "’ (-2.775) w opr .05 to .25 -0.229 (-0.765) w opr over .25 -.052 {-0.111) lnstrsj -0.271 ”" (-12.l62) proplg, 0.221 " (1.770) w depj 0.023 (0.979) Number of Obs. 233 R-squared .617 Statistically significant at 10% ‘, at 5% ”, at 1% ”"' 124 Table 26 Simple Correlation Matrix for Independent Variables Using Public Incumbent Markets There are 233 local market observations inthe sample. All 233 markets have only public incumbentfirmsinthematthebeginning onear—l. Tobeinthesample, Wal-Marthasto befirstseeninalocalmarketbetween 1981 -1994. W focj W debt, W oij W depj W ssqi Proplg; Mod Lnstrsj (1974 H311} $29.1 W foo) 1.000 W debt; .264 1.000 W 0W1}; .268 -.060 1.000 W dep, -.086 .072 .336 1.000 Wssqj .178 -.118 -.357 -.319 1.000 p (1974 M) PrOPlgL .030 .036 -.151 -.508 .057 1.000 Mod .186 -.105 -.372 -.369 .338 .125 1.000 Haj Lmtrsj -.163 .007 .166 .495 -.103 -.010 -.654 1.000 125 Table 27 Summary Statistics: Markets With All Public Incumbents Tobeinthesample,Wal-Marthastobefirstseeninalocalmarketbetween1981-1994. 233obs. Explanatory Mean Standard Minimum Maximum Variables Deviation w focj .7728 .1743 .0390 1.0 w delji .6660 .1145 .2935 1.0235 w owpi .0917 .1033 .0038 .5859 w depj .8047 % .8124 % .0437% 6.1587% w ssqi (1974M 59.4619 11.6496 15.5549 90.9609 Mg, .9315 .1519 0 1.0 mod Herfi .5079 .2342 .2099 1.0 lnstrsj 1.6003 .8055 0 3.5264 126 Table 28 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share at Year +2: Markets With Only Public Firms: Dependent Variable is Pen,- Dependent variable is the fiaction of total stores owned by Wal-Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 for all models (penj). All models are estimated using OLS with t-statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included in the specifications, but their coefficients are not shown. To be in the sample, Wal-Mart has to be firstseeninalocalmarketbetween 1981 -1994. Explanatory Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Coefficients Coefficients Coeflicients comtant 0.324 ” 0.239 ” 0.373 m" (2.426) (2.105) (2.882) WfOCj -0.116" - 0.145 ”* (-1.848) (-2.693) w debt,- 0.678 *” 0.701 ‘” 0.603 ‘” (7.269) (7.897) (6.880) w 0ij 0.026 0.0757 - 0.081 (0.327) (1.035) (-1.106) w depj 0.014 0.020 0.013 (0.923) (1 .467) (0.860) w ssqi - 0.001 - 0.002 ” (-1.055) (-2.087) proplg, - 0.036 - 0.007 - 0.055 (-0.455) (-0.100) (-0.706) mod hert} 0.240 ‘” 0.231 "* 0.216 t” (4.421) (4.283) (3.920) lnsn'sj - 0.091 W" - 0.096 ""' - 0.090 “W (6050) (-7.103) (-5.956) Number of Obs. 233 233 233 R-scLuared 0.64 0.63 0.63 Statistically significant at 10% *, at 5% ‘t, at 1% us 127 Table 29 Summary Statistics: Markets With All Public Incumbents Tobeinthesample,Wal-Marthastobefirstseeninalocalmarketbetween1981—1992. 176 obs. Explanatory Mean Standard Minimum Maximum Variables Deviation W foq .7522 .1829 .0390 1.0 W debt,- .6488 .1103 .2935 1.0235 W oij .0899 .1026 .0038 .5859 W depj .8147% .8619% .0437% 6.1587% W - 1914 60.6942 12.1748 15.5549 90.9609 Proplgi .9256 .1606 0 1.0 Mod Hert} .5191 .2335 .2222 1.0 Lnstrsj 1.5953 .7865 0 3.5264 "”7 128 Table 30 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share at Year +4: Markets With Only Public Firms Dependentvariableisthefiactionoftotalstoresownedby Wal-Martinlocal marketjatthe beginning of Year +4 for all models (penfivej). All models are estimated using OLS with t- statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included in the specifications, but their coefficients are not shown. To be in the sample, Wal-Mart hastobefirstseeninalocal marketbetween 1981 — 1992. Explanatory Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Coefficients Coefficients Coefficients Constant 0.197 0.005 0.221 t (1.401) (0.043) (1.700) w foo,- - 0.064 - 0.180 m (-0.763) (-2920) w debt,- 1.022 m 1.033 m 0.999 m (10.831) (10.386) (10.013) wowpj -0.069 0.119 -0.l39 (0.443) (0.889) (4.146) w depj 0.017 0.032 r 0.017 (1.029) (1.899) (1.015) w ssqj - 0.004 8* - 0.004 m (-2.477) (4.212) Proplg, - 0.053 0.008 - 0.060 (.0574) (0.094) (-0.689) Mod hat} 0.310 m 0.284 m 0.297 m (5.846) (5.198) (5.396) lnstrsj - 0.065 m - 0.081 m - 0.064 m (-3.649) (.4619) (-3.630) Number ofObs. 176 176 176 R-squared 0.64 0.63 0.64 Statistically significant at 10% ‘, at 5% “, at 1% "" 129 Table 31 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share in Year +2 as a Fraction of Stores in Market in Year —1: Markets With Only Public Firms DependeMvmiableisthefi’actionoftotalstoresatthebeginningonear-l inlocalmarketj owned by Wal-Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 (palbasq). The models is estimated using OLS with t-statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included in the spwification, but their coefficients are not shown. Explanatory Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Variables Coefficients Coefficients Coefficients Constant 0.538 ” 0.805 "‘ 0.620 ‘” (2.316) (4.192) (2.731) WfOCj -0.195 t -0.105 (-1.773) (-1.044) w debtj 0.350 "' 0.275 0.224 (1.935) (1.620) (1.559) w oij 0.005 -0.146 -0.l76 (0.031) (-0.801) (-1.069) w depj 0.017 -0.002 0.016 (0.681) (-0.098) (0.627) w ssqi 0.003 ” 0.002 (2.022) (1.384) Proplgi 0.197 0.109 0.165 (1.541) (0.916) (1.289) Mod hert} 0.456 ‘" 0.484 "* 0.415 ”" (4.971) (5.261) (4.283) Lnstrsj - 0.205 W" -0.188 *” -0.203 ”t (-6.763) (6789) (-6.720) Number of Obs. 233 233 233 R-squared 0.66 0.65 .65 Statistically significant at 10% *, at 5% "a at 1% m 130 Table 32 Simple Correlation Matrix for Independent Variables Using All Local Markets There are 471 localmarket observations inthe sample. Marketswithstoresownedby privatefirmsareincluded. Tobeinthesample, Wal-Marthastobefilstseeninalocalmarket between 1981 -1994. LBO,- Fracprij W depj W ssq; Proplgi Mod Hert} Lmtrsj (1974 gall-3) LBO 1.000 fi'acpri-l .2623 1.000 W dep; .0803 .4048 1000 W ssq; -.0725 -.0548 -.0548 1.000 "'7 1974(th Propl§_ -.0977 -.4972 -.5643 .0809 1.000 7 Mod -.1635 -.0708 -.2483 .1460 .2004 1.000 Heft} Lnstrsj .0765 .0206 .3577 .0174 -.l305 -.6843 1.000 131 Table 33 Summry Statistics: All local markets Tobeinthesample, Wal-Marthastobefilstseeninalocalmarketbetween 1981-1994. 471 obs. Explanatory Mean Standard Minimum Maximum Variables Deviation LBO dummy) .1125 .3163 0.0 1.0 flagprij .1434 .2233 0.0 1.0 w deL 1.5650 % 2.0305 % .0437 % 22.5768 % w . 1974”,, 59.2232 11.1508 15.5549 105.7653 M81 .8545 .1955 0.0 1.0 mod Hertj .4288 .2174 .1358 1.0 lnstrs) 1.8313 .7939 0.0 3.7842 132 Table 34 OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share: All Markets No Debt Ratio, No Focus Variable The dependent variable for Model 1 is the fraction oftotal stores owned by Wal-Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 (pent). The dependent variable for Model 2 is the fraction of total stores owned by Wal-Mart in local unrket j at the beginning of Year +4 (penfivej). The dependent variable for Model 3 is the number of stores owned by Wal-Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 as a fiaction of the total number of stores in local market j at the beginning of Year -1 (penbase,). All models are estimated using OLS with t-statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included in the E specifications, but their coefficients are not shown. To be in the sample, Wal-Mart has to be first ' seen in a local market between 1981 - 1994. Explanatory Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Coefiicients Coefficients Coefficients Y1: pent Yj= penfivei y1= penbusei Constant 0.6000 *" 0.681 ”"' 1.004 *” (9.708) (7.246) (3.462) LBO dummy; -0.00006 0.003 0.020 (-0.004) (0.126) (076$ fi-acprij -0.076 ” -0.121 t” -0.090 " (-2.469) (-2.860) (-1.842) w depj -0.001 -0.001 -0.003 (-0.474) (-0.l67) (-0.478) w ssqi -0.001 -0.001 0.003 ” (-1.491) (-0.856) (2.289) proplgj -0.027 -0.147 " 0.051 (—0.476) (4.852) (0.867) mod herf} 0.140 "" 0.212 ‘““ 0.401 t” (3.319) (3.617) (3.958) lnstrsj -0.095 ”“ -0.082 ’“ «0.196 “‘ (-10.017) (-5.767) (-8.892) Number of Obs. 471 370 471 R-squared .5195 .4121 .5789 Statistically significant at 10% ‘, at 5% ”, at 1% "" OLS Regressions Explaining Wal-Mart’s Market Share: All Markets. No Debt Ratio Thedependentvariable forbothModel l & Model 2 isthefiactionoftotalstores ownedby Wal- Mart in local market j at the beginning of Year +2 (M). Both models are estimated using OLS with t—statistics in parentheses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included in the specifications, but their coefficients are not shown. To be in the sample, 133 Table 35 Wal-Mart has to be first seen in a local market between 1981-1994. Explanatory Variables Model 1 Model 2 Coefficients Coefficients Y1: pen, Y1: pen,- (All Markets) (Public Markets) Constant 0.569 ”" 0.776 ”" (8.908) (4.774) fi’acprij -0.090 ”" (-2.734)) w ()pr- -0.285 ”‘ (-3.081) w focj 0.066 0.124 " (1.591) (1.877) w depj -0.002 0.023 (-0.552) (1.102) w ssqi -0.001 * -0.003 ”' (-1.821) (-2.753) proplg, -0.041 -0.063 (-0.698) (-0.547) mod hert} 0.144 ”‘ 0.141 "‘ (3.483) (2.421) lnstrs, -0.092 t" -0.105 ‘” (-9.231) (-6.008) Number of Obs. 465 233 R-s_quared .5236 .5154 Statistically significant at 10% *, at 5% ", at 1% "‘" _ 'IT I,“ uh"-"v a." I34 Table 36 Summary Statistics Observations for eachofthe50 States for eachyearwithin 1980- 1985. 8000bservations. Explanatory Mean Standard Minimum Maximum Variables Deviation Herf. .453 .141 .188 1.0 Infssga- (1974de 67.63 23.98 36.57 232.46 Propwal. 13.26% 18.61% 0.0% 75.25% Propwali. Sqd 5.21 10.35 0.0 56.62 135 Table 37 OLS Regressiom Explaining State Profitability and Herfindahls The dependent variable is shown at the top of the column below. The models are estimated using OLS with t-statistics in parmthsses using White’s consistent standard errors. Annual time dummies were included in the specifications, but their coefficients are not shown. There are observatiom for each ofthe 50 states for each year in the range of 1980 -1995. Explanatory DepVariable = Dep Variable = Dep Variable Variables infssqi. herfa Infssqg Comtant 33.029 ”" .464 "" 64.152 ”" (7.179) (23.236) (17.534) Herf. 65.211 ‘” (7.038) Propwali - 0.652 ”‘ - 0.622 ‘" (-10.315) (5.792) Propwal. 1.378 "“ 0.835 “" sqd (15.086) (5.563) Number of 800 800 800 Obs. R- Squared .2394 .132 .1242 Statistically significant at 10% r, at 5% n, at 1% m . B.‘ .— OI‘IIq‘FIL ”tire? .5.— APPENDIXB APPENDIX B — FIGURES Standard Disc. Dept. Store Sq.Ft per Person (U.S.) 3 2.8 2.6 . 2.2 2 . Q? 9‘? a? a? 61' 99 Calendar Year Figure] Standard Discount Department Stores Sales per Person (U.S.) Sources: U.S. Population from U.S. Census Bureau Industry Sales Data From Discount Merchandiser 136 137 Discount Department Store Sales Calendar 1975 lTop 5 Firms l Other Firms Figure 2 Fraction of 1975 Industry Sales By Top Five Chains Discount Department Store Sales Calendar 1 995 lTop 5 Firms lOther Firms Figure 3 Fraction of 1995 Industry Sales By Top Five Chains Source: Sales Data From Discount Merchandiser 138 1975 1985 1995 l. Kmart 1. Kmart 1. Wal-Mart 2. Woolco 2. Wal—Mart 2. Knnrt 3. Zayre 3. Target 3. Target 4. Vormdo 4. Zayre 4. Meijer 5. Korvette 5. TG&Y 5. Fred Meyer 6. Target 6. Bradlees 6. Marshalls 7. Fred Meyer 7. Fred Meyer 7. Caldor 8. TheTreasury 8. Ames 8. Ames 9. Skaggs 9. Caldor 9. Shopko 10. Fed-Mart 10. Marslmlls 10. Venture Figure 4 Top Ten Firms Based on Sales Source: Sales Data fi'om Discount Merclmndiser a V "" u—u '1 'n s I, - H Sauce:StoreLocationDataFromDirectoryofDisco\mtDepamnemStorss 140 Figure 6 Wal-Mart 1985 Store Locations Source: Store Location Data From Directory of Discount Department Stores 141 Figure 7 Wal-Mart 1990 Store Locations Source: Store LocationDataFrom Directory ofDiscountDepartment Stores I42 Figure 8 Wat-Mart 1996 Store Locaions Source: Store Location Data From Directory of Discomt Department Stores F iiiiii Source: Store Location Data From Directory of Discount Department Stores 144 ' oath-ammonia. an :2” ‘ cult—um . Figure 10 Wal-Mart and Sky City 1990 Store Locations Source: Store Location Data From Directory of Discount Department Stores 145 Figure 11 Wal-Mim and TG&Y Store Locations1977 Source: Store Location Data From Directory of Discount Department Stores harm ' ammonia“. w Figure 12 Wal-Mart & TG&Y Store Locatiom 1986 Source: Store Location Data From Directory of Discount Department Stores 147 Figure 13 Wal-Mart and Duckwall 1975 Store Locations Source: StoreLocationDataFromDirectoryofD’ncomtDepartmentStores 148 I I mm * ammonium . mm ' nun-antennas.“ Figure 14 Wal-Mart and Duckwall 1996 Store Locations Source: Store Location Data From Directory of Discount Department Stores LIST OF REFERENCES LIST 0]" REFERENCES Aggarwal, Rajesh, and Andrew Samwick, 1997, Executive compensation, and relative performance evaluation: Theory and evidence, working paper, Dartmouth College. Berger, Philip and Eli Ofek, 1995, Diversification’s effect on firm value, Journal of Financial Economics 37, 39-65. Bolton, Patrick and David Scharfstein, 1990, A theory of predation based on agency problems in financial contracting, The American Economic Review 80, 93-106. Brander, James, and Tracy Lewis, 1986, Oligopoly and financial structure: The limited liability effect, The American Economic Review 76, 956-970. Chen, Ming-Jet, and Donald Hambrick, 1995, Speed, stealth, and selective attack: How small firms differ from large firms in competitive behavior, Academy of Management Journal 38, 453-481. Chen, Ming-Jcr, and Ian MacMillan, 1992, Nonresponse and delayed response to competitive moves: The roles of competitor dependence and action irreversibility, Academy of Management Journal 35, 539-570. Chevalier, Judith, 1995, Capital structure and product market competition: Empirical evidence from the supermarket industry, The American Economic Review, 415-435. Chevalier, Judith, 1995, Do LBO supermarkets charge more? An empirical analysis of the effects of LBO’s on supermarket pricing, The Journal of Finance 50, 1095-1112. Comment, Robert, and Gregg Jarrell, 1995, Corporate focus and stock returns, Journal of Financial Economics 37, 67-87. 149 150 Demsetz, H., and K. Lehn, 1985, The structure of corporate ownership: Cause and consequences, Journal of Political Economy 93, 1155-1177. Directory of Corporate Affiliations Who Owns Whom, New Jersey: National Register Publishing., 1975-1990. Directory of Discount Department Stores, New York: Business Guides Inc.1975-1982, 1987-1994. Directory of Discount Stores, New York: Business Guides Inc., 1983-1986. Directory of Discount and General Merchandise Stores, New York: Business Guides Inc., 1995-1996. Discount Merchandiser, New York: Schwartz Publications, 1975- 1996. Fama, Eugene, and Michael Jensen, 1983, Separation of ownership and control, Journal of Law and Economics 26, 301-325. Fershtman, Chaim, and Kenneth Judd, 1987, Equilibrium incentives in oligopoly, The American Economic Review, 77, 927-940. Fudenberg, Drew and Jean Tirole, 1986, A “Signal Jamming” Theory of Predation, Rand Journal of Economics, 17 (3), 366-376. Jensen, Michael, and William Meckling, 1976, Theory ofthe firm: Managerial Behavior, agency costs and ownership structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3, 82-137. Kaplan, Steven, and Luigi Zingales, 1995, Do financing constraints explain why investment is correlated with cash flow? NBER Working Paper Series, 5267. Khanna, Naveen, 1998, Optimal contracting with moral hazard and cascading, forthcoming Review of Financial Studies. Khanna, Naveen and Annette Poulsen, 1995, Managers of financially distressed firms: villains or scapegoats? The Journal of Finance 50, 919-940. Kedia, Simi, 1997, Product market competition and top management compensation, working paper, New York University. 151 Kovenock, Dan, and Gordon Phillips, 1997, Capital structure and product market behavior: An examination of plant exit and investment decisions, The Review of Financial Studies 10, 767-803. Lang, Larry, and Rene Stulz, 1994, Tobin’s q, corporate diversification, and firm performance, Journal of Political Economy 102, 1248-1280. Maksimovic, Vojislav, 1988, Capital structure in repeated oligopolies, Rand Journal of Economics 19 (3), 389-407. Meyer, Michael, Paul Milgrom, and John Roberts, 1992, Organizational prospects, influence costs, and ownership changes, Journal of Economic & Management Strategy 1, 9-35. Mikkelson, W., and M. Partch, 1989, Managers’ voting rights and corporate control, Journal of Financial Economics 25, 263- 290. Million Dollar Directory, Pennsylvania: Dun & Bradstreet, 1975- 1996. Opler, Tim, and Sheridan Titman, 1994, Financial distress and corporate performance, The Journal of Finance 49, 1015-1040. Phillips, Gordon, 1995, Increased debt and industry product markets: An empirical analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 37, 189-238. Reitman, David, 1993, Stock options and the strategic use of managerial incentives, TheAmerican Economic Review 83, 513-524. Rotemberg, Julio, and David Scharfstein, 1990, Shareholder-value maximization and product market competition, The Review of Financial Studies 3, 367-391. Safieddine, Assem, and Sheridan Titman, 1997, Debt and corporate performance: Evidence from unsuccessful takovers, NBER Working Paper Series, No. 6068. Scharfstein, D., 1997, "The dark side of internal capital markets 11: Evidence from diversified conglomerates,” Working paper, MIT and NBER. 152 Scharfstein, D. and J. Stein, 1997, ”The dark side of internal capital markets: divisional rent-seeking and inefficient investment," Working paper, MIT and NBER. Song, Moon, and Ralph Walking, 1993, The impact of managerial ownership on acquisition attempts and target shareholder wealth, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 28, 439-457. Stein, Jeremy, 1997, Internal capital markets and the competition for corporate resources, The Journal of Finance, 52, 111-133. Value Line Investment Survey, New York: Value Line Publishing Inc., 1975-1996. Wards Business Directory, New York: Gale Research, 1987-1996.