I LIBRARY I Michigan State Unlverslty PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MTE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 1/98 WWW“ THE ROLE AND CONTRIBUTION OF FEDERALLY FUNDED BASIC RESEARCH IN PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION By Andrew A. Toole A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1 998 ABSTRACT THE ROLE AND CONTRIBUTION OF FEDERALLY FUNDED BASIC RESEARCH IN PHARMACEUTICAL INNOVATION By Andrew A. Toole Research and development investment is an important factor in technical progress and productivity growth. Recent theoretical research has suggested that the stock Of knowledge created through cumulative research and development feeds new innovation and economic growth. When knowledge creation is funded by public institutions, the research results are both non-rival and non-excludable. Non-rivalry means that the use of public research by one agent does not preclude its use by another while non-excludability guarantees that the results from public research are accessible to all agents. Because of these Characteristics, the public stock of knowledge can feed innovation across different sectors and industries in the economy. This dissertation analyzes the role and contribution of publicly funded basic research in pharmaceutical innovation. Drawing on conversations with industry scientists, it is argued that public funding of biomedical research facilitates advances in public scientific understanding and thereby creates new avenues to therapeutic outcomes and research opportunities for new drug discovery. As new opportunities emerge, private firms use this information in the pharmaceutical innovative process to develop new drug concepts and define therapeutic outcomes. It is in this manner that public basic research contributes to the discovery of new therapeutic compounds. The discovery of new compounds is modeled using the economic production framework. In this framework, basic research can make both a direct contribution to the discovery of new therapeutic compounds and an indirect contribution by stimulating private research and development (R&D) investment. The sum of these individual effects leads to an estimate of the total impact of public basic research on pharmaceutical innovation. The quantitative analysis explores the timing, magnitude, and significance Of the impact that public basic research has on pharmaceutical innovation and investment. A new panel data set is constructed using medical therapeutic Classes over time. Detailed data on Public Health Service awards between 1955 and 1985 are matched by therapeutic Class and year with measures of pharmaceutical innovation, industry R&D investment, Food and Drug Administration regulatory stringency, and pharmaceutical demand. The analysis finds strong evidence for an economically and statistically significant impact of public basic research on pharmaceutical innovation and investment. The total marginal impact indicates that a $1 million investment in the stock of public basic research produces 0.07 new chemical entities in each therapeutic class after an average of seventeen years. This would yield an average discounted cash flow of $14.2 million in each therapeutic Class at the time of introduction. Copyright by Andrew A. Toole 1 998 To Karen, Brittni, Kevin and my parents. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS First and foremost I would like to thank Karen for her incredible patience and understanding during the completion of this research. Brittni and Kevin were also supportive. Everyone helped in one way or another to bring this project to a successful close and I am very thankful and blessed to have them in my life. I would also like to thank my parents. Their endless support and positive attitude allowed me to overcome some of the darkest moments. My father listened to countless hours of “visionary economics” and helped me clarify my thoughts on many points. I am also in debt to John Goddeeris, Jeff Wooldridge, and Wally Mullin for making this research stronger and more rigorous. I thank each of you for encouraging careful work, providing timely feedback and supporting me over the several years of commitment that doctoral work requires. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ............................................................................................ ix LIST OF FIGURES ......................................................................................... xi CHAPTER 1 Introduction ...................................................................................................... 1 1.1 Overview .................................................................................................... 1 1.2 Plan of the Dissertation ............................................................................. 5 1.3 A Primer on Public Basic Research ........................................................... 6 1.4 Literature Review. Multi-Industry Studies ............................................... 10 1.5 Literature Review. Studies of the Pharmaceutical Industry .................... 13 CHAPTER 2 Basic Research and the Process of Pharmaceutical Innovation ................... 18 2.1 Overview .................................................................................................. 18 2.2 The Pharmaceutical Innovative Process: Standard View ....................... 18 2.3 Basic Research and FDA Regulation: Industry Interviews ..................... 23 2.4 Development of the Hypotheses .............................................................. 27 2.5 The Captopril Example ............................................................................ 32 CHAPTER 3 The Analytical Framework, Data, and Estimation Method ............................. 35 3.1 The Analytical Framework ....................................................................... 35 3.11 Issues Regarding Possible Endogeneity .................................... 39 3.2 Data Sources and Construction ............................................................... 42 3.21 Productivity Measure .................................................................. 43 3.22 Industry R&D Measure ................................................................ 44 3.23 Measure of Government Funded Basic Research ...................... 51 3.24 Measure of FDA Regulatory Stringency ...................................... 56 3.25 Measures of Pharmaceutical Demand and Medical Need .......... 58 3.26 Time Effects and Therapeutic Class Effects ............................... 62 3.3 The Estimation Technique ....................................................................... 66 3.31 The Direct Effect ......................................................................... 66 3.32 The Indirect Effect ....................................................................... 70 vii CHAPTER 4 The Direct Impact Of Public Basic Research on Pharmaceutical Innovation ............................................................................ 72 4.1 Overview .................................................................................................. 72 4.2 Model Specification ................................................................................. 75 4.3 The Timing of the Relationship ................................................................ 78 4.4 The Magnitude of the Public Research Impact ........................................ 85 4.5 The Statistical Significance of Public Research ...................................... 86 4.6 Alternative Depreciation Rates for Public Research ................................ 89 4.7 The Industry Elasticity and Net Present Value of Public Research ......... 90 4.8 Substitution Possibilities, Returns to Scale, and FDA Regulation ........... 94 4.9 Conclusion ............................................................................................... 97 CHAPTER 5 The Indirect Impact of Public Basic Research on Pharmaceutical Innovation: Investment in Response to Research Opportunities ................................... 100 5.1 Overview ................................................................................................ 100 5.2 Model Specification ............................................................................... 104 5.3 Functional Form ..................................................................................... 110 5.4 The Regression Results and Discussion ............................................... 112 5.41 Timing of the Relationship ........................................................ 112 5.42 The Magnitude and Significance of PHS Basic Research ........ 114 5.43 Public Regulation and Industry Demand ................................... 116 5 5 Wiggins (1983) Revisited ...................................................................... 118 5. 6 Endogeneity Test for Scientific Opportunity .......................................... 121 5. 7 Conclusion ............................................................................................. 125 CHAPTER 6 The Total Impact of Public Basic Research on Pharmaceutical Innovation .................................................................................................... 128 6.1 Overview ................................................................................................ 128 6.2 The Total Impacts .................................................................................. 129 6.3 Re-Cap Dissertation Findings ................................................................ 132 6.4 Future Research .................................................................................... 136 APPENDIX A Keywords Used to Construct PHS Basic Research Variables ..................... 138 APPENDIX 8 Regression Tables ....................................................................................... 144 LIST OF REFERENCES .............................................................................. 182 viii LIST OF TABLES Table 3.1 - Tabulation of Counted NCES ...................................................... 45 Table 3.2 — Descriptive Statistics on Counted NCEs by Therapeutic Class..46 Table 3.3 — Pharmaceutical Industry R&D (millions of 1986 $) ..................... 48 Table 3.4 - PHS Biomedical Basic Research (millions of 1986 S) ................ 53 Table 3.5 - Statistics on FDA Regulatory Delay Times (months) .................. 59 Table 3.6 — Pharmaceutical Industry Sales (millions of 1986 S) .................... 63 Table 3.7 - Incidence of Disease (hospital discharges in thousands) .......... 64 Table 3.8 — “Severity" of Disease (hospital days in thousands) .................... 65 Table 4.1 - PHS Basic Research (15% Dep.) Non-Nested Regression Results with 12 Year Industry Lag .............................................. 80 Table 4.2 - PHS Basic Research (15% Dep.) Non-Nested Regression Results with 14 Year Industry Lag .............................................. 81 Table 4.3 — PHS Basic Research (15% Dep.) Nested Regression Results with 12 Year Industry Lag .............................................. 83 Table 4.4 — PHS Basic Research (15% Dep.) Nested Regression Results with 14 Year Industry Lag .............................................. 84 Table 4.6 - 10% Depreciation - PHS Basic Research Non-Nested Regression Results for 12 Year Industry Lag ............................. 91 Table 4.5 - 20% Depreciation — PHS Basic Research Non-Nested Regression Results for 12 Year Industry Lag ............................. 92 Table 4.7 - CES Production Function Estimation .......................................... 95 Table 5.1 - Regression Results for the Indirect Effect of PHS Basic Research (15% Dep.) ............................................. 113 Table 5.2 - Re-Examination of the Wiggins Model ..................................... 119 Table 5.3 — PHS Basic Research ................................................................ 124 Table A1 - Listing of Class Filter Keywords or Character Strings .............. 139 Table A2 - Listing of Exclusion Filter Keywords or Character Strings ....... 140 Table A3 - Activity Code Breakdown ......................................................... 141 Table 81 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 15 ................................................... 144 Table 8.2 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 16 ................................................... 145 Table 8.3 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 17 ................................................... 146 Table 8.4 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 18 ................................................... 147 Table 8.5 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 19 ................................................... 148 Table 8.6 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 20 ................................................... 149 Table 8.7 — Industry Lag 14, PHS Lag 15 ................................................... 150 Table 8.8 - Industry Lag 14, PHS Lag 16 ................................................... 151 Table 8.9 — Industry Lag 14, PHS Lag 17 ................................................... 152 Table 8.10 - Industry Lag 14, PHS Lag 18 ................................................. 153 Table 8.11 - Industry Lag 14, PHS Lag 19 ................................................. 154 Table 8.12 - Industry Lag 14, PHS Lag 20 ................................................. 155 Table 8.13 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Nested 12,17,22 .................................. 156 Table 8.14 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Nested 9,17,25 .................................... 157 Table 8.15 — Industry Lag 14, PHS Nested 12, 17, 22 ................................ 158 Table 8.16 — Industry Lag 14, PHS Nested 19, 17, 25 ................................ 159 Table 8.17 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 15 (10% Depreciation) ................. 160 Table 8.18 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 16 (10% Depreciation) ................. 161 Table 8.19 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 17 (10% Depreciation) ................. 162 Table 8.20 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 18 (10% Depreciation) ................. 163 Table 8.21 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 19 (10% Depreciation) ................. 164 Table 8.22 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 20 (10% Depreciation) ................. 165 Table 8.23 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 15 (20% Depreciation) ................. 166 Table 8.24 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 16 (20% Depreciation) ................. 167 Table 8.25 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 17 (20% Depreciation) ................. 168 Table 8.26 — Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 18 (20% Depreciation) ................. 169 Table 8.27 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 19 (20% Depreciation) ................. 170 Table 8.28 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 20 (20% Depreciation) ................. 171 Table 8.29 — CES Estimation, Industry Stock, PHS Lag 17 ........................ 172 Table 8.30 - Indirect Effect, PHS Concurrent Lag ...................................... 173 Table 8.31 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 1 ...................................................... 174 Table 8.32 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 2 ...................................................... 175 Table 8.33 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 3 ...................................................... 176 Table 8.34 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 4 ...................................................... 177 Table 8.35 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 5 ...................................................... 178 Table 8.36 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 6 ...................................................... 179 Table 8.37 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 7 ...................................................... 180 Table 8.38 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 8 ...................................................... 181 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1.1 — Basic Research Funding (real 1987 S) ........................................ 8 Figure 1.2 - Public Health Service Study Sections, Activity Codes and Institutes ...................................................................................... 9 Figure 2.1 — The Pharmaceutical Innovative Process (Source: Bloom (1976)) ............................................................ 19 Figure 2.2 - Where Basic Research Fits into the Pharmaceutical Innovative process ..................................................................... 28 Figure 2.3 - Captopril Example ..................................................................... 33 Figure 3.1 - Cardiovascular, Anti-infective and GastrolGenito-urinary Counted NCEs ........................................................................... 47 Figure 3.2 - Cardiovascular, Anti-infective and GastrolGenito-urinary Industry R&D (millions of 1986 S) .............................................. 49 Figure 3.3 - Cardiovascular, Anti-infective and GastrolGenito-urinary PHS Basic Research (millions of 1986 S) .................................. 54 Figure 3.4 - Cardiovascular, Anti-infective and GastrolGenito-urinary FDA Review Times (months) ..................................................... 60 Figure 3.5 — Cardiovascular, Anti-infective and GastrolGenito-urinary Industry Sales (millions of 1986 S) ............................................ 63 Figure 3.6 — Cardiovascular, Anti-infective and GastrolGenito-urinary Hospital Discharges ................................................................... 64 Figure 3.7 - Cardiovascular, Anti-infective and GastrolGenito-urinary Disease Inpatient Days .............................................................. 65 Figure 4.1 — Pharmaceutical Innovation Levels with Slower Real Basic Research Funding Growth (0.06% slower) ...................... 87 xi Chapter 1 Introduction ...the most important aspect of research management is the ability to access the scientific information emanating from academic and industrial laboratories throughout the world, to discern its importance, and to integrate it rapidly into our research. Edward M. Scolnick, MD. President of Human Health at Merck & Co., Inc. 1 .1 Overview Following World War II, the United States Government established itself as the leading financial supporter of basic research. Fueled by the belief that a strong basic research foundation would lead to productivity increases and greater national welfare, federal funding of basic research grew at a real annual rate of 11.8% through the 1960s. However, beginning with the economic challenges of the 1970s and the concomitant pressures on the Federal budget, policy debates resulted in the reduction in the growth rate of federal funding for basic research. For the 1970-1989 period, the real annual growth rate dropped to 2.8% (NSF (1992)). It is evident from current and past debates that competing demands for federal funds have caused policy makers to re-evaluate national research policy. The traditional belief in basic research as a means to increase national and industrial production has been questioned. At least in part, this policy debate is perpetuated by a shortage of economic analyses describing and quantifying the impact of federally funded basic research. Since basic research is that research which builds fundamental knowledge within a scientific discipline, its connection and contribution to industrial innovation is less obvious than applied research and development. Nevertheless, the impact of basic research can be examined using the standard production relation described in the economics literature. The production framework identifies two related channels through which federally funded basic research can influence industry innovation. First, basic research can contribute directly to private industry's product innovation. In this case, basic knowledge is used as a direct input to create the new product introduced by private industry. For example, pharmaceutical firms use the basic research results on biological and chemical processes to conceive therapeutic outcomes and synthesize new therapeutic compounds. Second, federally funded basic research can contribute indirectly to private industry's product innovation. This indirect contribution recognizes the role that basic knowledge plays in stimulating additional private R&D investment. Often times additional private R&D is needed to strengthen and extend the foundation of knowledge created by public financing. Accounting for both the direct and indirect effects leads to an estimate of the overall impact of federally funded basic research on industrial product innovation. In general, US. support for basic research has gone to universities and colleges to fund academic research. A recent survey by Mansfield (1995) reports that federal funds constitute two-thirds of the total research dollars used by academic researchers. Outside of the agricultural sector, econometric analyses of basic research have focused primarily on the link between academic research and manufacturing innovation and productivity. In this vein, several probing multi-industry studies have been done in recent years. Jaffe (1989) uses the production framework to estimate the elasticity of corporate patents with respect to the stock of academic research spending. Grouping industries and academic departments into "technological areas," Jaffe finds that academic research makes a significant contribution to commercial innovation. Using Jaffe's model and a measure of new business innovation, Acs et al. (1991) also find that academic research contributes to industry innovation. Adams (1990), using knowledge stocks constructed with weighted counts of journal articles, finds that fundamental knowledge either increases or decreases manufacturing productivity depending on the lag specified. Although the generality of the multi-industry approach is one of its strengths, it is also one of its weaknesses. It is difficult to infer from these studies how basic research has impacted an individual industry. The best we can do is acknowledge the general importance of this research to the various technological areas studied. As will be seen below, our focus on an individual industry motivates the mapping of research between sectors and allows us to control for industry specific characteristics. Moreover, previous studies do not distinguish between federal and non-federal funding sources. In order to gauge the impact of federally supported basic research on industrial innovation and gather information for policy evaluation and formulation, we must explicitly analyze the impact of this research. This dissertation provides an estimate of the “total impact” of US. Government funded basic research on pharmaceutical innovation by combining separate estimates of the direct and indirect effects. Using insights gained from interviews with industry scientists, the analysis begins by describing the role of basic biomedical research in the pharmaceutical innovative process. This qualitative discussion provides the basis of the four primary hypotheses tested in the empirical analysis: first, public basic research has a positive and significant direct impact on pharmaceutical innovation; second, public basic research has its greatest impact in the formulation of "drug concepts" which come in the earliest stage of drug discovery; third, the distinctive contributions of public basic research and private industry R&D to the pharmaceutical innovative process suggest limited substitution possibilities between these two types of research; and fourth, public basic research indirectly impacts pharmaceutical product innovation through its affect on industry R&D investment. Furthermore, the potential for increasing returns to scale in pharmaceutical innovation and the effects of product quality regulation by Food and Drug Administration (FDA) are also explored. This study introduces basic research by therapeutic class into the economic model of pharmaceutical innovation. The data used to measure basic biomedical research consists of all extramural grant and contract awards given by the Public Health Service (PHS) between 1955 and 1985. The PHS funds the largest portion of all basic biomedical research, whether one considers public, private, or both sectors. In 1985, the PHS financed 80% of all US. Government obligations for national health R&D, covering 66% of all non-industry funding (NIH data book (1989)). Further, this study incorporates two key characteristics Of basic research. First, basic research is allowed to be cumulative over time. This captures the important quality of Ieaming that builds on previous research knowledge. Second, basic research is lagged so that its hypothesized timing can be tested and explored statistically. The federal awards data are combined with standard measures of pharmaceutical innovation, industry R&D expenditure, and regulatory stringency. Approved new chemical entities (NCEs), a measure of important patents, are used to represent pharmaceutical innovative success. Industry R&D expenditure figures were obtained from the Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers Association (PhRMA). The FDA supplied the necessary data to calculate measures of regulatory stringency. 1.2 Plan of the Dissertation Chapter two describes the role of public basic research in the pharmaceutical innovative process and outlines the main hypotheses to be tested. Chapter three presents the general modeling framework, describes the data and discusses the estimation techniques. Chapter four describes the empirical specification and results of the direct impact of public basic research on pharmaceutical innovation. Chapter five presents the empirical specification and results of the indirect impact of public research on pharmaceutical innovation. Chapter six concludes the analysis and calculates the total impact of publicly funded basic research. 1.3 A Primer on Public Basic Research An important part of understanding the relationship between federally funded basic research and industry innovation is understanding the institutional base from which this research is created. In general, the stock of public basic research is the output of the US. national research enterprise. The US. national research enterprise is the set of government, industrial and academic institutions that conduct research in the United States. With respect to basic research, the US. national research enterprise essentially refers to the aggregate of US. academic institutions. Under federal sponsorship, the academic research enterprise has grown into a tremendously diversified institutional base supplying the largest portion of the stock of public basic research. The National Science Foundation defines basic research as that which is directed toward “a fuller knowledge or understanding of the subject under study, rather than a practical application thereof” (NSF, 1985, P. 221). It is the research which builds fundamental knowledge within a scientific discipline. The definition of basic research used in this study encompasses the NSF definition but also adds that the research must be non-clinical and relevant to the pharmaceutical industry. Figure 1.1 plots overall federal basic research expenditures and the PHS basic research awards (across all classes) used in this study for the years 1960 - 1985. For comparative purposes, both series are presented in real 1987 dollars using the implicit GDP deflator. It is worth noting that the PHS awards trend is not characterized by the rapid increases and decreases that are evident in the trend of overall federal basic research funding. The Public Health Service is the key governmental body in charge of the allocation of federal research money for biomedical and pubic health projects. This is accomplished through the use of “study sections” or peer review groups which recommend approval of grant applications. Each recommended grant will have an activity code which describes the nature of the proposal in broad terms such as research, fellowship, training, etc. The set of recommended applications are sent on to get final committee approval from the particular institute that will fund the study. Figure 1.2 plots the total number of PHS activity codes, the number of institutes and the number of study sections from 1955 to 1985. There are two interesting points with regard to this plot. First, the rapid expansion of PHS funding through the 19603 is evident in the growth of the number of study sections, activity codes and institutes during this period. Likewise, the steady-state which characterized the 19708 is also evident. Finally, it is important to remember the public goods aspect of federally financed basic research. Projects funded with federal monies are part of the cocaomem 23m wIa l+l 583mm 23m .825“. =< IAYI 3 “we .3: 059.5... cocmowcm 06mm - : 9:9“. ozonQezozezQQQQQQ zoe@%e(o(a(e(o(%oo%eooo T, r TLTT- TLITT TL.-- .T-+l+ +LI TITLni ITTTITTI o \+ l+tl+ I+.€.....+I+I+I+I+I+ I +l+l+\+l+l+r Tilt/f ooow so?c oooo - .. ooom - oooow . ooom F 8.2.3:. .25 880 5.2.94 @8595 Sam 8.28 5.8... 2.8.. - we 9:9“. Av! Av! 01 Au! 1. I. I. 0v. 0. I? as coco «90 coco 8552..— u a mmuoo Ed.“ I mm». I 00.. om; .. DON 0mm 10 public domain. As such, the results of this research add to the public stock of knowledge and possess two key characteristics: non-rivalry and non- excludability. Non-rivalry means that the use of public research by one agent does not preclude its use by another while non-excludability guarantees that the results from public research are accessible to all agents. Because of these characteristics, the public stock of knowledge can feed innovation across different sectors and industries in the economy. 1.4 Literature Review: Multi-Industry Studies The focus of this dissertation draws on two lines of research in the economics literature. The first is the literature regarding the measurement of spillovers from government and academic research to industry research and development. In this vein, the central focus has been on studying multi-industry flows. Mansfield (1991) uses survey data from 76 firms in seven manufacturing industries, one of which is the ethical drug industry, to look at the extent to which technological innovations have been based on recent academic research; the time lags between academic research discoveries and commercial utilization; and the social rate of return from academic research. Mansfield finds that the drug industry has the highest percentage of new products and processes that could not have been developed (without substantial delay) in the absence of recent academic research. However, his study was not designed to produce an 11 estimate of the extent of these spillovers. A second study directed by Mansfield appears in his book, Research and Innovation in the Modern Cormration, published in the early 19708. In the chapter on the ethical pharmaceutical industry, Jerome Schnee identifies the discoverer of sixty-eight drug innovations spanning two separate time periods, 1935-1949 and 1950-1962, and presents some descriptive statistics. One of the major conclusions of this exercise is that academe, as a source of drug innovations, has accounted for fewer drug discoveries relative to industry sources over time. He defines discovery as the first identification of a drug's biological activity. That is, he considers the first identification of the therapeutic action of the drug. Link (1981) appears to be the first study to analyze the impact of government financed basic research on industry productivity. The analysis separates both company financed and government financed research into applied and basic portions. Using data from fifty-four manufacturing firms, Link finds that government financed basic research has a positive and significant effect on total factor productivity. His elasticity estimate for government financed basic research is 1.17. However, it is important to note that Link measures direct government payments to the firms themselves and not the stock of public research available outside of the firms. Jaffe (1989), in an important study relating academic research to industrial research, looks at the spatial relationship between academic and industrial research and development. It belongs to a class of R&D spillover models that use some measure of "technological distance" separating the origin and 12 destination (the receiving industry) of the innovation. He estimates a three dimensional simultaneous equation panel data model in which observations are indexed by state, "technological area," and time. The innovative output measure is corporate patent counts and the innovative inputs are measures of industry and academic R&D expenditure aggregated to the level of the technological area. Importantly, Jaffe distinguishes between basic and applied R&D in his analysis. He finds significant spillovers from university R&D to industrial R&D. While the multi-industry Character of his study is both a strength and weakness, his work serves as an important step in understanding the relationship between external knowledge and commercial innovation. Adams (1990) is a multi-industry study of the relationship between manufacturing total factor productivity and academic research. There are three unique elements to his analysis: first, he uses a labor weighted count of journal articles to measure the stock of “fundamental” knowledge; second, he analyzes the lag between the research and its impact on productivity; and third, he includes knowledge stock measures of within industry knowledge and external knowledge. Although he finds that fundamental knowledge either increases of decreases manufacturing productivity depending on the lag specified, the data reveal that the “science only” spillover lag is about thirty years. 1.5 Literature Review: Studies of the Pharmaceutical Industry The second line of research consists of those studies which focus exclusively on the pharmaceutical industry. This research falls mainly into two camps: studies of FDA regulatory stringency and studies of research investment and productivity. With regard to the studies of FDA regulation, Martin Baily (1972) and Grabowski et al. (1978) (GVT) estimate the direct effect of regulation using [new chemical entities/R&D] as their measure of pharmaceutical productivity. Having a continuous dependent variable, they use OLS to estimate their models. The only difference in their approaches is that GVT use the United Kingdom as a control for non-regulatory factors. There are three important non-regulatory factors identified: the thalidomide disaster; advances in pharrnacologic science; and the depletion of research opportunities. The idea of the depletion of research opportunities is of direct interest. Baily attempts to capture this using a moving average of past NCE introductions; however, GVT show that this measure is insignificant when a larger sample period is used. GVT prefer to use the UK. as a control for the relationship between basic biomedical research and pharmaceutical research by assuming that advances in basic research affect both the US. and UK pharmaceutical industries the same. The final important point regarding the GVT analysis is their method of measuring the regulatory stringency. GVT use the mean time from submission of the new drug application to approval in each year of their sample. Their sample covered 1954-1974. 13 14 Wiggins (1979) expands on this work in two ways: (1) he estimates the relationship for each therapeutic class;1 and (2) he estimates the total effect not just the direct effect. Wiggins notes the importance of “scientific knowledge” in the pharmaceutical firms’ decision process. In fact, he states, “In conclusion, it must be reemphasized that the most important consideration [in choosing a research project] is still the scientific one.” (Wiggins, 1979, p. 69) This being said, Wiggins has no way to account for changing scientific knowledge nor can he estimate its relationship to pharmaceutical drug innovation. Similar to GVT, Wiggins uses the mean time from NDA submission to approval for each class for each year. Finally, because Wiggins uses NCES as his dependent variable, he uses a Tobit estimation technique in an attempt to account for the truncation at zero. Using firm level data, Jenson (1987) improves on the estimation technique for the model by using a Poisson specification along the lines of Hausman, Hall, and Griliches (1984). She uses the same measure of regulatory stringency as GVT and includes a time trend and other interacted variables in an attempt to account for scale economies in pharmaceutical R&D. Econometrically, Jenson maintains the nominal variance assumption of the Poisson model (that is the mean = variance property of the Poisson distribution). Jenson does inspect the off diagonal elements of the covariance matrix formed using the standardized residuals for evidence of serial correlation and concludes 1 A therapeutic class is a grouping of compounds based on their treatment indication. 15 that it “does not appear to be a serious problem.” Her results indicate that regulatory stringency decreases the expected number of new chemical entities while firm size has no significant affect on the marginal productivity of research expenditure. There are two existing studies that focus on pharmaceutical research effort and productivity: Ward and Dranove (1995) and Henderson and Cockbum (1996). Ward and Dranove measure R&D spillovers from government—funded basic research to pharmaceutical applied research. The authors are interested in the magnitude and lag structure characterizing R&D spillovers between basic research and applied research. They construct a panel data set of therapeutic classes covering the period 1966-1988. They measure spillovers in two ways. First, by regressing industry R&D expenditure on a count of journal articles and other variables, they find that a 1% increase in journal articles results in a 0.22%—0.36% increase in industry R&D expenditure. Second, the authors regress industry R&D expenditure on the National Institutes of Health (NIH) obligations broken-down by institute and aggregated, as closely as possible, into therapeutic classes. Within the same therapeutic class, a 1% increase in NIH obligations leads to an increase in industry R&D expenditure by 0.57%-0.76% (cumulative over all lags). Further, an "indirect" spillover is associated with NIH obligations in other therapeutic classes. This effect has industry R&D expenditure increasing 1.26%-1.71% in response to a 1% increase in NIH obligations. Two things are important to note about the Ward and Dranove analysis. 16 First, their study explores the determinants of R&D inputs not outputs. Consequently, while this study is interesting and informative, the role of R&D spillovers in the successful deveIOpment of usable output remains an open question. Presumably, the spillovers of inputs contribute to individual firm success in drug development by either reducing cost or increasing the likelihood of success by providing better leads in drug discovery. Second, the NIH funding data that they use consists of the total obligations of the NIH for a particular institute in a given year. Research obligations correspond to present and future funding commitments while awards measure the actual financial outlays in a given year. Although there is not much difference between the two, using obligations might affect the timing of the relationship since obligations typically lead awards by one year. Henderson and Cockbum (1996) look at firm specific economies of scope and scale as well as inter-firm spillovers in the drug discovery stage of pharmaceutical R&D.2 They use disaggregated proprietary firm data at the level of the research program. It is organized as a panel data set which contains detailed R&D input (investment) data from ten pharmaceutical firms spanning a period of twenty years. Innovative output is measured by a count of "important" Composition of Matter patents. This is defined as a patent granted after the discovery stage of research in two of three major markets. 2 In the Henderson and Cockbum analysis, economies of scope exist within the firm if physical assets or personnel can be used in more than one application at no extra cost. Economies of scale exist if fixed costs can be distributed over a 17 Their analysis incorporates both direct and indirect inter-firm spillovers. Direct spillovers occur between firms that are involved in research in the same therapeutic class. For instance, this is the case when two firms both conduct R&D on drugs for the cardiovascular system. Indirect spillovers between firms are those which occur across related therapeutic classes. In this case, research on blood and blood forming organs may uncover a result useful in cardiovascular drug R&D. Both measures were found to have positive and significant coefficients indicating the presence of inter-firm spillovers. larger research effort or if the firm can hire specialized researchers as their total research effort grows. Chapter 2 Basic Research and The Process of Pharmaceutical Innovation 2.1 Overview This chapter develops the qualitative basis for the hypotheses that are tested in the empirical section of the dissertation. The chapter begins with a description of the standard schematic of the pharmaceutical innovative process. As will become clear, this schematic does not explicitly describe the role and contribution of public basic research in the discovery and development of new therapeutic compounds. To gain an understanding of where basic research fits in the pharmaceutical innovative process, previous research is supplemented by interviews with industry scientists and administrative personnel. Following a description of the interview responses, a new schematic showing the role of basic research is presented and the four main hypotheses regarding public basic research are described. The chapter ends with a description of the discovery of captopril, an example of how public basic research can contribute to pharmaceutical innovation. 2.2 The Pharmaceutical Innovative Process: Standard View Figure 2.1 gives a detailed breakdown of the pharmaceutical innovative process. This process is divided into two broad stages: drug discovery and 18 A85: E85 .8509 $805 o>:m>o:c_ _mo_SoomE.m.._n_ of. .. ...N 959”. 19 OZ— m3o_>om ‘II (on. beam .3 5.529"... .952 38%. .8 :o_fi:_m>m .mE_c< £8556 $289.0 MOE—nuan— fihmmmmm 008.305. 20 um>o=£ Rosana—ESE DE SE SE £0383. Diem 22;? - Nd EsmE ¢ 565.com Egan Eoiéo Z BBZE moi—620m . EoEEoEO “3:309:00 . 33:35 . Good 28 88m IV 388m maroofiwcm 5.833— 850 3282—0 . Diem BBZE 98 235m wE—oooz 5253 838m DDSQEoU . 58885 . 5:3: 0:95 mica—Him 3252.0 E850 wen :oSomcm 06.3 0:95 .8 03on 29 locate government, and private nonprofit institutions.‘ This analysis focuses on PHS funded extramural basic research. The PHS accounted for 80% of US. Government funds for national health R&D in 1985, which is 66% of all non- industry funding (NIH data book (1989)). Of the remaining 34% of non-industry health R&D, other federal institutions account for 17%, state and local government account for 11% and private nonprofit institutions make up 6%. In terms of basic research, the NIH (a component of the PHS) accounts for 39% of all federal basic research obligations with 67% going to colleges and universities. Economic analysts have just recently begun to investigate the relationship between advances in medical science and the pharmaceutical industry (Henderson(1994), Grabowski and Vernon (1994), Henderson and Cockbum (1996), and Gambardella (1992, 1995)). Using a detailed example drawn from cardiovascular drug discovery, Henderson (1994) argues that those pharmaceutical firms which possess a greater ability to integrate research information have a competitive advantage in the industry. Grabowski and Vernon (1994) note its importance in the rise of biotechnology firms. Henderson and Cockbum (1996) and Gambardella (1992) analyze research spillovers between firms and describe how public medical research has improved the screening process used in drug discovery. ‘ To a much lesser degree, publicly available basic research results also come from firms within the industry and foreign sources. lntra-industry sources are small and subject to long lags due to the high degree of secrecy regarding research opportunities while little is known about foreign sources. 30 Unlike previous analyses, this study focuses on the empirical relationship between the stock of publicly funded biomedical research and drug discovery. Since this is the dominant funding source creating the research that feeds drug concept development, public basic research serves as a core driver of industry innovation. Although specifying the mechanisms through which public research is monitored, integrated and utilized by pharmaceutical firms is a high research priority, the first step toward understanding begins with identifying, measuring, and testing the broader empirical importance of this relationship. Our objective is to test the timing, magnitude and significance of the impact that public research has on pharmaceutical innovation and industry R&D investment. When combined with the qualitative evidence, this objective leads to the following testable hypotheses concerning core knowledge created by publicly funded basic research: Hyppthesis 1: Core knowledge produced by public basic research funding has an economically and statistically significant direct effect on pharmaceutical innovafion. Hypothesis 2: Core knowledge produced by public basic research funding feeds the drug concept stage of industry research and, therefore, has its greatest impact in the earliest stages of drug discovery. Hypothesis 3: The distinctive contributions of public basic research and private industry R&D to the pharmaceutical innovative process suggest limited substitution possibilities between these two types of research. Hyppthesis 4: Core knowledge produced by public basic research funding has an economically and statistically significant indirect effect on pharmaceutical innovation by inducing industry R&D investment. 31 Like public basic research, FDA regulation can have a direct effect on pharmaceutical innovation and an indirect effect on innovation through its impact on industry R&D expenditure. In studying each of these effects much of the previous economic research has used average NDA review times as a proxy to measure the impact of regulatory stringency on pharmaceutical innovation (Grabowski and Thomas (1978), Wiggins (1981 ,1983) and Jensen (1987)). Using lags of review times to account for changing expectations concerning FDA review criteria, these studies find that regulation has a negative and significant impact on pharmaceutical innovation up to five years prior to NDA submission. However, these studies also focused on FDA review data covering the 19603 and 19703. In light of the interview results that claim the industry is adjusting to FDA regulation earlier in the innovative process, one would expect that the direct impact of FDA review times on innovation would show up in lags greater than five. To account for this, the cumulative direct impact of FDA regulatory stringency is allow to extent nine years prior to an approved NDA. The indirect effect of regulation is more problematic. Some studies, Wiggins (1981,1983) and Jensen (1987), find NDA review times reduce industry R&D investment while a more recent study, Ward and Dranove (1995), finds that NDA review times increase industry R&D investment. In the former studies, longer FDA review is interpreted as reducing the number of candidate compounds entering the innovative process while, in the later study, longer FDA review times are interpreted as leading to increased expenditure on those projects already in process. Aside from covering different sample periods, there is one 32 notable methodological difference: Instead of using observed average review times, Ward and Dranove (1995) use the predicted review times from a first stage regression. By reducing the random variation in the review times measure, it seems the Ward and Dranove approach should lead to a more precise estimate rather than a change in the sign of the estimate. Nevertheless, each of these findings is theoretically possible. 2.5 The Captopril Example There is a growing case study literature describing the successful interaction between public biomedical research and private industry R&D (see Maxwell et al. (1990), Gambardella (1992, 1995), Henderson (1994), and Henderson and Cockbum (1996, 1997). Although each story is unique in its details, there are two major themes that emerge. First, public research knowledge develops or matures into a body of knowledge that can be extended and utilized by the pharmaceutical industry. Second, private industry is in a position to transform public basic research into new compounds. The story of captopril illustrates these themes. Captopril is an important drug for regulating blood pressure. Figure 2.3 illustrates that captopril inhibits the conversion of angiotensin I to angiotensin II. It is referred to as an ACE inhibitor because it blocks the conversion to angiotensin II and thereby prevents high blood pressure. The scientists at Squibb synthesized captopril in the early 19703. The patent was granted in 33 cafiaxm 23390 - mN ocswi MOEMEIZH m0< 238$ coo—m All All 2555 $53250 Al .3: = _ 52.3635. :_m:86_w=< 34 1977, which is the same date as the publication of their research underlying its discovery. In 1981, the FDA approved captopril for market sales. Notwithstanding the creative work of the Squibb scientists, their discovery is built on two lines of public research. The first line involved the identification and description of the renin-angiotensin system. While this public research dates back to at least 1934, it was the late 19503 when the key scientific papers which identified angiotensin I and angiotensin II were published. The second line of important public research originated in Brazil. Research into the cause of death from snake venom identified a natural substance which acts on its victim by fatally lowering blood pressure. In 1965, it was shown that this natural substance blocks the conversion of angiotensin I to angiotensin II. Thus, armed with this public knowledge, the scientists as Squibb were able to discover and develop a drug for human consumption that Iovvers blood pressure. The discovery of captopril illustrates several points. First, the advance of public basic research knowledge can open up new avenues to therapeutic outcomes. This knowledge can be used directly in the discovery of new compounds. Second, basic research is cumulative and reaches some maturity point as which private firms can usefully apply their skills. There is a lag between this “critical point” and the ultimate FDA approval of a new compound. If one were to describe the study published in 1965 as the critical point, then the lag between the key public research discoveries and FDA approval of captopril would be sixteen years. Third, it was the combination of public basic research and private industry R&D that created this new therapeutic compound. Chapter 3 The Analytical Framework, Data, and Estimation Method 3.1 The Analytical Framework This analysis uses the production framework to model pharmaceutical technology and new drug innovation. This framework has been used to study the impact of research and development on innovation by Pakes and Griliches ( 1984). Their “knowledge production function” (KPF) model has also been used to study knowledge spillovers from academic research to corporate patents (Jaffe (1989)) and manufacturing innovation (Acs et al.(1991)). While these models take patent counts as their metric of innovation, this analysis uses a measure of important patents as its metric of innovation. Important patents in the pharmaceutical industry are defined as the number of approved new Chemical entities. Recent research by Henderson and Cockbum (1996) use the KPF to analyze a measure of important pharmaceutical patents. The KPF is particularly well suited for an investigation of pharmaceutical innovation due to the industry’s research intensive Character. It focuses on the relationship between research expenditures and innovation. One limitation of this framework, however, is its reduced-form approach. Many of the complex interactions and details of the pharmaceutical innovative process are not explicitly modeled. The lack of sufficiently detailed public data prevents the specification of a more sophisticated structural model. Nevertheless, the KPF 35 36 provides a useful framework to extend our understanding of pharmaceutical innovation and to provide evidence on the impact of government funded research. The KPF is used to estimate the direction and magnitude of knowledge spillovers or transfer from public medical research to pharmaceutical innovative output. This type of productivity relationship is not embodied in a purchased product but instead in the free communication of useful research results. The model utilizes the “therapeutic class” as its map between federally funded research and industry research and output.1 The therapeutic class is a grouping of compounds based on their treatment indication and has been used by the Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers Association to group industry R&D since the early 19603. For example, cancer basic research is grouped and related to industry cancer drug research and not to industry cardiovascular drug research. To capture the differences across therapeutic Classes, an individual intercept (indexed by the subscript i) is specified for each , 2 of seven therapeutrc classes. 1 Although federally funded basic research can be usefully grouped into therapeutic classes, these classes are not always mutually independent. Occasionally, basic research from one class will feed the discovery of compounds in another class. 2 The classes considered in this study are: endocrine/neoplasm, central nervous system, cardiovascular, anti-infective, gastrointestinallgenitourinary, dermatologic, and respiratory. These classes cover over 80% of the industry R&D investment. 37 The general form of the direct relationship determining pharmaceutical innovation is represented as: (30 Yn=qmbfime where i represents the medical therapeutic class, t represents time, Yit is a count of pharmaceutical innovative output, 'it is industry R&D, Bit is the stock of Public Health Service funded basic research, Rit is FDA product quality regulation. The empirical specification of the functional form, q, will be discussed in chapter four. Based on the qualitative discussion in chapter two, the expected signs of the partial direct effects (marginal productivities) are: <11 >0.Q2>0.<13<0 The first relation, q1 > 0, is the expectation that industry R&D increases pharmaceutical innovation. The second relation, q2 > 0, is the statement of hypothesis one discussed in chapter two. That is, public basic research contributes to pharmaceutical innovation by providing new avenues to therapeutic outcomes and facilitating the chemical screening step of drug discovery. The third relation, q3 < 0, is consistent with previous research on FDA regulation that shows increased regulatory stringency reduces pharmaceutical innovation. 38 In addition to the direct production relationship, basic research and regulation have an indirect effect acting through their influence .on industry R&D investment. The pharmaceutical investment decision is modeled using a net present value (NPV) framework. While the details of this model are discussed in Chapter five, the structural investment relation can be summarized as follows: (3.2) 'it = g (Bib Rit: Expected Demand“, Cost of Capitalt) where subscripts i and t represent therapeutic class and time, respectively; Bit and Rit are defined as in equation (3.1); Expected Demandit are other explanatory variables affecting the rate of return to pharmaceutical investment by influencing the expected revenue stream, and the cost of capital variable(s) account for the influence of the opportunity cost of capital. The NPV model and each of the explanatory variables will be discussed fully in chapter five. Here, the expected partial effects are: 91 >0.92<0.93>0.94<>0 The first relation, 91 > 0, corresponds to hypothesis four of chapter two. This is the inducement effect of public basic research on pharmaceutical R&D. The second relation, 92 < 0, follows previous research on FDA regulation that shows increased regulatory stringency reduces pharmaceutical investment. The third relation, 93 >0, states that increased expected demand for pharmaceutical compounds in a therapeutic class will lead to greater industry R&D investment. The final relation, 94 <> 0, indicates that the cost of capital can either increase 39 or decrease investment. Generally speaking, a fall in the cost of capital implies greater investment since more projects become profitable. The estimate of the total effect of basic research is calculated by estimating the direct effect (chapter four) and the indirect effect (chapter five) separately and combining the results to calculate the total effect (chapter six). The overall or total effects of government funded basic research and FDA regulation on pharmaceutical innovation are given by: (int/dBrt)=q2+91*91 ( int / dRit ) = C13 + (:2 *92 where the subscripts represent partial derivatives of the indicated functions. Combining the expected signs of the partial effects discussed above implies the following signs on the overall impact of public basic research and FDA review times: (int/dBit)>0 (dYIt/dRit)<0 3.11 Issues Regarding Possible Endogeneity The theoretical production function model embodied in equation (3.1) defines the direction of causation as running from the inputs to outputs. This 40 means that industry R&D, government funded basic research and FDA regulation all combine to cause the flow of pharmaceutical innovative output, Yit- Yet it is reasonable to believe that innovative output may spur or cause changes in any three of the defined inputs. For example, a newly approved drug by one firm may cause other firms to undertake related research and, hence, stimulate industry R&D. For basic research, a new FDA approved drug may spur greater academic interest in exploring some biological process and, consequently, cause some academic researchers to write up and submit grant proposals for federal support. For regulation, a previously approved drug may begin to show negative long-term side-effects that cause the FDA to review and possibly change its approval criteria. In all of these cases there is feedback from the pharmaceutical innovative output to future values of the input variables. Econometrically, we are saying that the input variables are not strictly exogenous. Failure of strict exogeneity can be the cause of inconsistent estimators (see Wooldridge( 1994) and Blundell et al. (1995)) . However, this analysis does not impose strict exogeneity. The pooled estimation technique used to calculate the direct effect allows for feedback of an arbitrary nature from current realizations of the dependent variable to future values of the explanatory variables. The direction of causation postulated between industry R&D investment and government funded basic research in equation (3.2) has been subject to some debate among researchers. The current research literature on spillovers points out the possibility that a bias may arise due to Changes in "scientific 41 opportunity." That is, researchers have noted that a promising development in a particular scientific discipline may lead to correlation between industry and public R&D funding that is not correctly characterized as spillovers. It arises when research funding agents respond to the same “scientific break-through” information when making their funding decisions. Further, if scientific opportunity is a problem , then estimates of the relationship between public and private funding of research are biased by the endogenous response of funding agents. One way to conceptualize the scientific opportunity problem is as an omitted variable bias. In this scenario, equation (3.2) has an omitted “scientific opportunity” variable and, consequently, the basic research variable is endogenous. This would lead to bias and inconsistent estimates of the parameters. As a practical matter, any bias due to scientific opportunity will always be a possibility in models of research spillovers. In our context, the issue rests on three basic questions. First, how fine a line can be drawn between basic research and applied research? The National Science Foundation definition provides a broad guide to follow when delineating between the two; however, it does not allow one to construct mutually exclusive sets of research. To the extent that public and industry research overlap, the possibility of a scientific opportunity bias remains. As with the present study, researchers must use great care when breaking research projects into separate categories. Second, at what stage of research “maturity” is the promising development in the scientific discipline? A fundamental assumption in models of 42 R&D capital is that R&D is effective over many periods and has an evolutionary Character; Ieaming and research are cumulative processes that are best measured as stocks. One idea underlying the model of equation (3.2) is that there exists some level of research maturity at which point basic biomedical research becomes useful to pharmaceutical drug discovery. A scientific opportunity bias is less likely when the academic researcher and the industry researcher focus on different areas of research. Third, what proportion of pharmaceutical research effort is devoted solely to the exploration of basic science? Although an exact figure is not publicly available, pharmaceutical firms do conduct basic research. By all accounts it is a small but growing element of the industry’s research strategy. Again, to the extent that research overlaps, a scientific opportunity bias is possible. Although it is expected that any bias related to scientific opportunity would be minimal in this analysis, chapter five explores the endogeneity issue between industry R&D and public basic research. 3.2 Data Sources and Construction The well known difficulties of measuring the spillover or transfer of knowledge across sectors has made the data collection and preparation a very important aspect of this project. The three primary sources of data, the Public Health Service, Food and Drug Administration, and the Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers Association, are matched by year and therapeutic 43 Class.3 Together these sources represent the most recent and comprehensive public data available to address the hypotheses in this paper. 3.21 Productivity Measure The measure of innovative output, Yits is a count of new chemical entities (NCES) approved by the FDA. These are defined as new molecular compounds that have never before been tested or used in humans. The FDA supplied the data on approved NCES for the years 1960-1994. As used here, the counts of NCES exclude diagnostic and certain biological agents, new dosage formulations, surgical and other materials such as contact lens and devices. To construct the counts of NCEs, the FDA data were grouped by year of approval and therapeutic class. Although the year of approval was supplied by the FDA, the compounds had to be assigned to the various therapeutic classes. This was accomplished by using the clinical pharmacology and treatment indication descriptions from the Physician’s Desk Reference, Merck Index, and Martindale The Extra Pharmacopoeia. These sources were also used to eliminate any compounds not fitting the definition of NCES used in this project. 3 Each measure used in this analysis has been grouped according to the therapeutic classification scheme used by the US. Department of Commerce Current Industrial Reports, Pharmaceutical Preparations except Biologicals. 44 Both the tabulation of counted NCE and some descriptive statistics by therapeutic class are presented in Table 3.1 and Table 3.2, respectively. Figure 3.1 graphs the number of counted NCES against time for the cardiovascular, anti-infective and gastrolgenito-urinary classes. Although NCES are only one possible productivity measure of pharmaceutical innovation, DiMasi et al. identify NCES as the “most therapeutically and economically significant” (DiMasi et al. (1991), p. 108). Of course, patents are the traditional indicator of economically productive knowledge in KPF types of studies. It should be kept in mind that even though simple patent counts are an alternative, approved NCEs are a measure of economically important patents because they have proven therapeutic value. “Important” patent measures address one of the key criticisms of patent measures as an indicator of innovative output—the wide variation in the economic value of individual patents (Griliches (1984)). Trajtenberg (1990) provides an informative discussion on this issue. 3.22 Industry R&D Measure The public data on pharmaceutical industry R&D expenditure, 'it. come from the Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers Association’s Annual Survey Report. Domestic US. company-financed R&D expenditures for human- use (dosage form) ethical drugs were obtained for the period 1963-1994. Table 3.3 presents summary statistics for industry R&D for 1963-1994 while Figure 3.2 45 Table 3.1 - Tabulation of Counted NCEs Year Total Number of Number of Number of Other Number of] Approved Material and Diagnositc Repeat Excluded Counted NCES Device NCES NCEs DosagLe NCES NCES NCES 1964 24 1 0 0 1 22 1965 12 0 0 0 0 12 1966 18 0 0 4 1 13 1967 22 0 0 3 0 19 1968 9 0 1 0 0 8 1969 17 0 2 1 0 14 1970 20 0 0 0 0 20 1971 16 2 1 0 0 13 1972 11 0 2 1 0 8 1973 28 1 11 2 0 14 1974 36 3 3 0 0 30 1975 20 0 1 5 0 14 1976 26 1 9 0 0 16 1977 21 3 1 0 0 17 1978 20 2 2 0 0 16 1979 14 1 0 0 0 13 1980 12 0 0 0 0 12 1981 25 0 3 0 0 22 1982 28 0 5 0 0 23 1983 14 0 1 0 0 13 1984 20 0 1 0 0 19 1985 28 0 3 0 0 25 1986 19 0 2 0 0 17 1987 20 0 3 0 0 17 1988 19 0 3 0 0 16 1989 22 0 2 0 0 20 1990 22 0 4 0 0 18 1991 30 0 0 0 0 30 1992 32 0 3 5 0 24 1993 24 0 3 0 0 21 1994 22 0 4 0 0 18 —Totals 651 14 70 21 2 544 46 m9: dddm ddd mod? on 099. Ed? on d 2mm; ..(Bommflo =< Ed cod ddd Ed ddN ood Ed dod dod Eodgaom and cod ddd dud 2: Odd omd cod dod 03229500 Ed... cod cod 9N Odd cod Eé 8.? Odd Bactsogcow>«52.252590 and cod cod and cod cod ddN ooE ddd $2685-22 Nod ooE ddd mod 09E cod v ...F 006 ood 53035.0th 56 cod do... and cod dd... 3.0 ood ddN Sufism m30202 .9200 EEd cod ddé d w d CON do._. end cod do... Emu—moozEctooucm 2o_2mo - fin 2:9“. vamp Nmm— camp name wmmw vwmw Name mum? ohm? ticsow N59. Ono? » a 48 $00 N 00.0nvm $N— .0 0v.000v $v0 .0 000000 $ 5.0 00 .00: 00306 =< $00.0 0 .00 _. $00.0 NO0N0 $v0.0 00. Fm? $0NNr N000 0.900300”. $00.0 00.05 $000? 00;: $000 N700 $00.0? 0N; 20.299500 $3 .0 0v.00F $00 .N 00.00N $00K 00 .0: $00 .0 N550 b0c_59_c00\_0:6000505000 $00.0 00 dov $NN .0 50 NNO $00.0 V0 00¢ $~.0 N 00.0NN 0020000: 12.2 $00 .0 r0. :0 $004. 0.1.: F $0 F Ne 0v.00v $vnd Nth .m_:omm>o_EmQ $ 3.0 00.000 $00.0w 00.0v0 $00N 0v.000 $NNO 00.00N E00050 mu30202 _0=c00 $00K 0NON0 $ ..NNP 00 .0 For $NON 309‘ $00 .v 00. SN Emm_0002\0ctoo.ucm 000m 539.0 00m 0002 0.0m 5390 00m c005. 0001 530.0 0.0m c005. 000m 526.0 0.01 c005. v00 7009 .50 7000? 000 Tmmmw 0N0 7000—. 0006 033000.02» A0 000? 00 205E: 0.0m b00305 503308.5ch - 0.0 030... 49 A0 002 00 mco==EV 0.0m b00305 b0c_5.o:c0m¥ozmmmu 0cm 028005-006. 0030092200 - N0 050E .ll.l .l «l .I: sll.v.!l l Illl l .. ll|.ll ll. l..l .50.. 000? 000' 50— 000— 000? 000—. soar @00— 000. v8? 000' N02 30— 0009 0kg 0kg Rae 0&2 chap fla— T!.|1l . .lTIIllTI- -.JT + l. 0 f .r llll+ll f . . T [r i 4 l 8.0 I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I . 8.8“ I I I . i . \ l‘ Dex-0+ \ll . .7 880 .51! + . . . , 0.2.0ch \ .. 88.. 50 graphs industry R&D against time for the cardiovascular, anti-infective and gastrolgenito-urinary therapeutic classes. Perhaps the biggest problem with the PhRMA data is its level of aggregation. Firms are aggregated into industry figures to protect the strategic position of individual firms. Moreover, the R&D investment totals are a composite measure of industry resources used in drug discovery and development (the cost of manufacturing appears to be in these figures as well). The PhRMA definition of R&D investment is as follows: The total cost incurred for all pharmaceutical research and development activity, including cost of salaries, other direct costs, service, routine supplies, and supporting costs, plus a fair share of overhead (administration, depreciation, space charges, etc.). Cost of drugs or medical research and development conducted on grant or contract for other companies are excluded. Conversely, total outlays for all research and development work contracted to others (manufacturers, independent research laboratories, academic institutions, etc.) are included. (PhRMA, Annual Survey Report) Consequently, due to the nature of the industry data, nothing can be said about the relative productivity of individual components of industry R&D expenditure. Therapeutic class totals were computable for most years in the data. Although yearly totals were always available, some therapeutic class totals had to be imputed (this amounted to five individual years of data). All figures include expenditure on research failures as well as expenditures in both discovery and development. Further, these figures were adjusted for inflation using the Biomedical Research and Development Price Index (BRDPI) supplied by the National institutes of Health. 51 3.23 Measure of Government Funded Basic Research The annual federally funded basic research flows were constructed from a comprehensive data set which includes all extramural grant and contract awards by the US. Public Health Service since l955. For each grant and contract award, the data includes: the title, the identification number (activity code, institute code, and grant or contract number), the fiscal year of award, the award amount, and the scientific review group that recommended its approval. The individual grant level data allow the construction of annual flow and stock measures of PHS research awards by therapeutic class. The final set of research projects, called “core” research, consists of all those scientific studies that represent basic research relevant to the pharmaceutical industry. Of the PHS research grants, basic research excludes non-medical, instrumentation and clinical (human) studies.4 Beginning with the total set of grants and awards for an individual year, the annual basic research flow series are constructed using several data filters. Four main filter levels are defined and used. The first eliminates awards based on activity code. Generally speaking, this filter purged activities such as training, education, construction, demonstration, and institutional block grants from the data. The second filter eliminates awards based on institute code. 4 Industry scientists helped with the data construction process due to the complexity of medical scientific terminology. 52 There are several institutes or divisions that contribute nothing or only a negligible amount to core research. Examples of eliminated institutes include the National Institute on Dental Research, the National Institute on Environmental Health Sciences, the National Library of Medicine, the Food and Drug Administration, and several others. The third filter eliminates scientific review groups that consider research outside the definition of core basic research. These groups are reviewed in every year and the filter is modified to be year specific. (This was necessary due to the splitting, adding, and discontinuance of scientific review groups over time.) The fourth filter level, which is really a group of filters, analyze awards based on keywords contained in the title of the grant or contract. This group consisted of seven keyword “inclusion” filters that help identify awards belonging to specific therapeutic classes as well as an “exclusion” filter designed to further sift out inappropriate awards missed in the earlier levels. The primary sources of information in the construction of the class filters are the Department of Commerce Current Industrial Reports and medicine’s scientific vocabulary. Table 3.4 shows the mean expenditure and growth rate by therapeutic class over the sample period (all figures are in millions of 1986 dollars). Figure 3.3 plots PHS basic research flows against time for the cardiovascular, anti-infective and gastrolgenito-urinary classes. Appendix A contains an explanation and copies of worksheets and filter programs used in the data construction effort. The filter levels separate the total universe of PHS grants into seven therapeutic classes of core research and a group of all other research. For a 53 $30 ~38 $3... 5.5: $m§ 8.8m $6.8 8.8.. 3330 __< $8.8 $2 $8... $8 $0: 2.8 $5.8 8... 32938”. $3.0 8.0 $3... E.» $Bm- go $2.3m one 2.0.23.8 $23 8.3 $93 8...: $2.0 Rem? $2.8 8.8 52.500828..mscafimo $2.: 8.2: $30 «$8 $05 $0.3 $8.8 No.2 32.8.5.2... $80 2.5. $30. 30.0% $2 .N 8.0? $8- 8.3 5336.28 $3... 3%. $30 «$8 $8.0 8am: $m§~ 3.5 505.6 «.8202 .9050 $98 5 .mmm $m . .m 58m $03 2 .mmm $2.. E 8.9: 58.082.05.820 Sum 5390 0.8m 322 2mm 5390 28m :85. 2.2. £2.90 0.3m :85. 23. 5590 05mm :82 $2.82 32.32 mg 0-82 82-82 $8.0 c.5399: A0 000? 00 2.05:5 20.00030 2000 60.00890 01““. - v0 0300. .0 000. mco_.__E. 20.0000”. 0.000 0.5 00556....0990000 0cm 0>_60.c_-_.c< 003803.200 - 0.0 050.“. 000w 000' ..00. 0N0? Row 0N0? 0&0? 2.0. 000? N00? 000.. 000.. «00? 000? N00. 000.. .l-|T|:T| .l |+ll.+l. ..l-i+l ll-Tli .l-T- -+- 1+ ll ll+ -..-f - 0 lfl ..T: ITllTlllii » .« + l T _ 080 II I\. U . . L-qu.00 . +\ . 39.0.6: . . . . . . \ .088. + I I .5 . . . . . 8‘ 2050+ . . . . . . . . . l‘lr . $83. I . , 95.80 .9680 55 class total, the awards are summed across all grants. This is a simple method that does not attempt to apply different weights to individual research projects based on “importance” or scientific discipline. Having completed the construction of the annual basic research series the next step is to construct the cumulative stock measure, Bit. used in the analysis. The government funded basic research stock is created using the standard perpetual inventory model described by Hall et al. (1988). For each therapeutic class, the stock of basic research is given by: (3.3) Bit = (Annual Flow)“ + ( 1-8 )*( Bit-1 ) where Bit is the stock of PHS funded basic research in class i and year t, (Annual F low)" is the annual flow of PHS funded basic research in class i and year t, and 8 is the depreciation rate of “knowledge capital”. With 8 constant over time we are assuming a geometric form of depreciation. In this case, a given year’s flow of basic research losses its “productive capacity" at a constant percentage rate each year. Using a 15% rate of depreciation we see a 48% decline in the productivity of basic research over four years. In the literature, Hall et al. (1988) assume a 15% depreciation rate of R&D capital and Henderson and Cockbum (1996) use a 20% rate. The sensitivity of the estimated coefficient to changes in the rate of depreciation is explored in chapter four. The geometric form has the additional property that assets never “retire.” Unlike the case of physical capital, this makes sense when applied to research 56 capital (it avoids the issue of having to estimate the useful life of research results—which we expect are long anyway). To implement the perpetual inventory model the stock measure must begin at a benchmark. The benchmark for the Bit variable is the year 1944. This is the year Congress passed the Public Health Service Act authorizing the surgeon general to award research grants. Using the 1955-1985 sample growth rate by therapeutic class, the annual flow series were projected back to 1944. These nominal flows were also adjusted for inflation using BRDPl. Finally, equation (3.3) is used to construct the stock series. 3.24 Measure of FDA Regulatory Stringency Since the passage of the 1962 Kefauver-Harris amendments to the Federal Food, Drug and Cosmetic Act of 1934 economists have been interested in the relationship between regulation and pharmaceutical innovation. The two most popular approaches are: first, to use a proxy variable for FDA regulation (Ward and Dranove (1995) and Wiggins (1979, 1981)), and second, to use the international residual from comparing the US. experience with that of the United Kingdom. The studies in the second group assume that US. firms and UK. firms differ only in their regulatory environment (Grabowski et al. (1978)) or that they differ in their regulatory environment after controlling for firm size (Thomas (1990)). They ignore the possibility of that public knowledge can affect pharmaceutical innovation. While the technical determinants of pharmaceutical 57 innovation are just beginning to be understood, it is clear that the public stock of basic biomedical research is one such factor. The contention that UK. pharmaceutical firms have the same access as US. firms to US. Government funded biomedical research is unsubstantiated. In fact, there is some interesting research on the role of geography in mediating knowledge spillovers (see Jaffe (1989) and Trajtenberg et al. (1993)). Moreover, Gambardella (1992) presents some initial evidence that public research results may be utilized with different degrees of effectiveness depending on firm human capital. This paper follows the first approach by specifying a proxy variable for FDA regulation. In particular, it uses the same method of measuring regulatory stringency as Wiggins (1981). In his method, firms are assumed to form expectations of regulatory stringency based on current and past observed delays between the submission of a new drug application and its final FDA approval. These average review times are calculated by year and therapeutic class. The therapeutic class distinction is appropriate since it corresponds fairly well with the review structure of the FDA. Using the new chemical entity data supplied by the FDA the review times are calculated for each approved NDA in months. The appropriate therapeutic class for each compound was determined in the process of constructing the NCE productivity measure. For those years in which no approved NDA is observed in a particular therapeutic class it is assumed that firms adjusted their expectations by increasing or decreasing the last observation in that class by the change in the overall average review time across all classes. The resulting regulatory 58 measures capture the cost associated with NDA review segment of FDA regulation. Table 3.5 shows the minimum, maximum and mean delay times by therapeutic class over the period 1973-1994. Figure 3.4 plots average FDA delay times by year for the cardiovascular, anti-infective and gastrolgenito- urinary classes. 3.25 Measures of Pharmaceutical Demand and Medical Need The expected demand for a therapeutic compound in an important component of the investment decision for pharmaceutical firms. It is the firm’s forecast of actual sales over the life cycle of the therapeutic compound. Informal interviews reveal that many firms purchase expensive market information that is specific to individual market segments within therapeutic classes. Purchased market data is combined with firm specific information on product characteristics and sales infrastructure to estimate the revenue stream. The main variable used in this analysis to proxy for expected demand is actual industry sales by therapeutic class and year. Wiggins (1983) and Henderson and Cockbum (1996) also use industry sales to proxy for demand. Sales by therapeutic class convey information on current market size, including demand from chronic medical conditions, as well as the distribution of industry sales resources (human and physical). This makes actual sales an important variable for conveying information about the market. Human-use, dosage-fonn ethical pharmaceutical industry sales figures broken down by therapeutic class 59 0500 {.09 00.00 00.2. 00.00 00.00. 00.00 (.00.. R00 00.0..ng 0.10 00.00 050 00.vm 00. 3 05.0 0 F NV 00.00 0....0F 0.0220650 50.00 0509 00.0 00.00 00.9. 00.0 00. ’0 0500— 00.0? 00c..aogcoo\.0c.mc2c.ofi0o 9.00 00.03 00.0 00.8 00.9 8.0 00.00 00.03 00.0. wo>.60.c.-.E< 5.0V 00.0NF 00.0 0 00.00 0N.00 00. E 00.00 00.00? 00.0 F 030090.200 00.0w 0». F I. 00.0 000v 004K 00.0 00.00 05 P : 00.0? 50.000 030202 .0950 00.00 00.00 00.0 V 05.00 00.00 00. : N000 00. P0 00.0.. Efiaoozxmcgoucw :02). 838.585. 53.55.). C005. 535.58.). EJEE...‘ c022 E:E.x0.2 5255.2 «$1.8. :8 EB. km 2.8. 23.0 0.5892h 3585. 85: 58 $0.38”. <9. 8 8.0.50 - mm 033 . _. 33? 60 v00. .259... 8E.» 3.5. <9. races-ogcuoasso .25 9.6%....2 53892.23 - ...m 2%: 82 «8. 52 82 82 82 $2 82 82 3.: 82 4.2: .2: 82 22 as. E... 2.: as. :2 2.: + 0 . T . 4. l4 0 0 LI 0' . .r . Till+l.. JT-- Fl . T o , . l ..8 5" I. . . t A. . . 4‘ . 1.. . ..8 agcll .51.. +8 3900+ -8. .8. 61 are available from PhRMA.5 Table 3.6 shows the mean and growth rate of industry sales from 1971 to 1985. Figure 3.5 graphs the series for the cardiovascular, anti-infective and gastrolgenito—urinary classes. In addition to industry sales, disease incidence and “severity” measures are developed. Data on the incidence and “severity” of disease are supplied by the National Discharge Survey. This survey covers non-Federal short-stay hospitals and is collected from a national sample of hospital records of discharged inpatients. Although the survey dates back to 1965, a fairly consistent time series is only available since 1971. It should be noted, however, that a new classification scheme was introduced in 1979. The lntemational Classification of Diseases, 9th Revision, Clinical Modification (lCD-9-CM) replaced the earlier edition. This change caused a small shift in some of the therapeutic class totals. A simple count of first-listed diagnoses, which are equivalent to the number of discharges, are grouped by therapeutic class and year. These counts represent the incidence of disease requiring short-stay hospital visits for the civilian non-institutionalized US. population. “Severity” is measured by a count of the number of hospital inpatient days. The basic notion is that more severe illness requires longer hospital stays. Because the hospital sample is inflated to estimates for the civilian non-institutionalized US. population, each of these 5 Industry sales to Federal hospitals were purged from the annual sales totals prior to computing therapeutic class totals. As an empirical matter, this correction had no effect on the results discussed in chapter five. 62 counts cover most of the US. population. The measures are less accurate for the older segment of the population since many senior citizens move to nursing homes. Tables 3.7 and 3.8 present the mean and growth rate of disease incidence and severity by class for 1971-1985, respectively. Figures 3.6 and 3.7 plot disease incidence and severity against time for the cardiovascular, anti- infective and genito-urinary therapeutic classes. Before turning to the estimation methodology for the analysis, it is important to note a few limitations with these measures. First, disease incidence is measured not disease prevalence. Since incidence measures the number of new cases over a period of time, it is not equivalent to prevalence, which measures the number of disease cases at a point in time. Although these concepts differ, incidence may be a good substitute for disease prevalence. Second, measuring severity by the length of hospital stays is fairly crude. In fact, the length of stay may be more related to the recovery period of illness or surgery. 3.26 Time Effects and Therapeutic Class Effects Time effects have been treated inconsistently in the current research on pharmaceutical innovation. Some researchers, such as Ward and Dranove (1995), do not include a time trend in their model while other researchers, such as Henderson and Cockbum (1996) and Thomas (1990), do not specify a full set of year dummies in their analyses. Dating back to Bailey’s analysis, all 63 a 82 a 20.55. 8.8 $89.. 225-2...8358 2.... 3.835%... 5.28:2an - on 2:9“. 08' v8. 08’ map .80 08* 050. 2.0— K? 0B0. 050. 3.0. 9.00 «mg {.0— . + . +111.-.- -- 1T1 .....-T.. ..-l .1.--- .1.- -.-.+ 1..-1.-+...1.---. .11 1+ I- +111 8.0 104.1019. 8.8m =c<|+lu 0.28141- \.\ \ +\.\ 33... 00.8%! 8820 __< $80 8.43.. 028.800 :3... 408... 0323.8 #80 2.3.... aoctaogcao=mc_mco.c_ofia0 $3.... 8.080 $832.35. $20 no.3.“ 5383.28 #8.» a .08; 522.0 3952 .258 $3... 2.83 5308235685 30¢ 539.0 00.0% 0002 new 7:2 80.0 25322: 3 82 .o 25%... 8.8 .382. 8.5835,... - a.» 0.8» $90235 .933... Emacs-2.50.2300 2.0 03.83:.-.05 003038.200 - 0.0 2:9“. l l ll lll-l lll ll l l lll llll ll Ill 111 .l. ll - :-ll . 1(- l -l111|. l mom. 4mm. mom. mom. Pom. one. mum. aka. 55m. one. mumr 40m. mum. «km. rum. Ti 4.- T- L. .-l-lT -1111T1l- T- 1-- + 1-1-1+ l 11.1-1-1. ---1. 1+1- .1..lT-lll+ ill... 0 .. 88 .1 p p p T p r +1 l . . . L.lll|+/..lll.T T . . . +l\\-. 0000 20:01? El _I 11 DOOM LE . . . . . . . . . . q . ._ ..ss . . . . . + 88 . . -- 88 -- 82 $80 02.8 830.0 .2 $20 83 322.8% $3...- omw gagsaémo $00.0- 000.0 02.52.50:053252.000 $00.0 50. F m0>..om.c.-=c< 08; 08;. 0.333.200 350.0 V006 805.6 26202 .2230 $20 mam...” Emmaoozwctooucm 20m 5320 :022 000.32.? 30.0 0.52.0.2.» $2532.. :. 00909.86 .5335 303.0 .0 8:00.05 - 50 033 65 90o E00000. 00000.0 300.560.503.030 0:0 002000.505 003305.200 - N0 050.”. wear 3a.. 08.. Nmmw 5a.. 89 mm? 059 KB. mum? mumr 3.2 009. N59. Km? 1 -1. 11 13.! .11-T-1- .511. 0 TI TI- TTI. -1- T11 501.- T+111 - T- .1 +1.. 1 1| |11114 i - 0080 $00.0 5 F00:— 00000.0 ..< $00. _. 3.0.0— 520.300”. $3.0. F0~.~ oaoT§0E00o $3M. 000.~N 30000005002055.0500 $550 30.: 0020000505.. $0 to 000.00 050003.200 $00.. 03.00 E00000 000202 .00000 $00.0- RN00 800.802.05.805 200 5320 :85. 000 7 :0 .. 000.0 0.50qu .0283... a. 0.2. 3085 00000.0 .o .2550. - 0.0 030» 66 indications are that time has an important and somewhat unexplainable impact on pharmaceutical innovation. In light of this fact, the current analysis specifies individual year dummy variables. Allowing each year to have its own intercept is the most general way to account for variation over time due to inflation, industry shocks, and other unobserved changes. As discussed above, the therapeutic classes provide the mapping of research knowledge used in this paper. Each of these classes encompasses the research from a cross-section of medical disciplines. Depending on the distribution of industry research investment as well as scientific and managerial skill, one class may feed into drug discovery more easily than another. For this reason, it is important to include some control for therapeutic class effects. This has been done using fixed-effect dummy variables for each class. 3.3 The Estimation Technique 3.31 The Direct Effect Since approved NCEs only take on non-negative integer values, a discrete dependent variable model is appropriate. In this analysis the conditional expectation of approved NCEs, E[NCEit| Xit], is assumed to be generated by a Poisson process for each therapeutic class, i, and each year, t. The Poisson distribution has been the workhorse of the empirical literature studying innovation counts. Due to advances in the econometrics literature on count 67 variable estimation, the actual conditional distribution of approved NCEs is not restricted to the Poisson form. In particular, the model can be estimated without imposing any restriction on the conditional variance of approved NCEs. The robustness properties of the estimation method are discussed below. The Poisson parameter, A“, is represented as a exponential function of all explanatory variables, X, and the parameters, b, as follows: (34) EINCEitI Xit] = 711t= exp(Xitb) where i indexes therapeutic class, t indexes time, an X are the explanatory variables. There are two important time series characteristics that must be considered when estimating models for panel data. The first is the strict exogeneity assumption discussed in section 3.11. Once again, the estimation technique used in this analysis does not impose this assumption. Second, dynamic models that do not include lagged dependent variables are not necessarily “dynamically complete.” The dynamic completeness assumption says that the model specifies the lag structure correctly so that further lags add no new information: (3.5) E(NCEitI xitvl’it-1s"it-1v--) = E(NCEit| xitvxit-1:---:Xit-k) where Yit—1 are lagged dependent variables, xit are the explanatory variables and, possibly, lags of other variables. Since there is no guarantee that dynamic 68 completeness holds, serial correlation is not ruled out. A Lagrange multiplier test is used to identify serial correlation in the model that may arise due to neglected dynamics in the conditional mean. Based on the results of this test, the heteroscedasticity and serial correlation robust asymptotic standard errors are calculated following Wooldridge (1991). A pooled quasi-maximum likelihood estimation technique (QMLE) is used to estimate equation (3.1). The technique is quasi-likelihood because the specified likelihood function, a Poisson likelihood function in this case, is not required to correspond to the actual distribution of the explained variable (NCEs) conditional on the explanatory variables, X. This leads to certain robustness properties. For instance, the actual distribution need not have the exact properties of the Poisson distribution, such as the mean equals the variance. In fact, Gourieroux, Monfort, Trognon (1984) show that an entire class of quasi-likelihoods in the linear exponential family (LEF) produce consistent estimates for the parameters of a correctly specified conditional mean. It is important to note that the Poisson QMLE produces consistent estimates under any variance assumption and arbitrary serial correlation in the observations. Under reasonable assumptions, the Poisson QMLE is relatively efficient. The asymptotic variance was estimated under three alternative assumptions about the conditional variance of E[NCEit| xid- The first method is “fully robust” in that it is valid under any conditional variance (or distributional) assumption (Wooldridge (1996)). The second method, the Generalized Linear Model (GLM) assumption, requires that the conditional mean and variance be proportional. 69 This requirement is represented as follows: (3.6) Var[NCEit| X11] = (:2 E[NCEit| X11] Where 02 > o The assumption implies that the ratio Var[NCEit| xit] l E[NCEit| xit] is constant but allows them to be different from each other by some positive number. The case where 02 > 1 is referred to as overdispersion whereas the case when 02 < 1 is called underdispersion. If there is overdispersion in the model, then the GLM standard error will be larger than the MLE and the resulting test statistic will show lower significance levels. The third method is the most restrictive because it requires the Poisson nominal variance assumption to hold. (37) VarINCEitl Xitl = EINCEitl Xit] This assumption imposes a standard property of the Poisson distribution, namely that the first and second moments of the distribution are equal. In most cases, Poisson models that do not relax the nominal variance assumption find spuriously high levels of significance. In the standard cross-sectional problem, calculating the standard errors under these three alternative conditional variance assumptions would be all that is needed for correct inference. However, models that incorporate a time dimension need to account for possible failure of the dynamic completeness 70 assumption. Under the GLM variance assumption, a Lagrange Multiplier statistic was computed to test for serial correlation. For equation (3.1), the test statistic is computed by estimating the model under the null hypothesis of dynamic completeness; calculating weighted residuals and weighted explanatory variables; running an auxiliary regression of these weighted residuals on the weighted explanatory variables and lagged weighted residuals. If k lags of residuals are included in the auxiliary regression, then this is equivalent to testing for kth order serial correlation. The sample size multiplied by the uncentered r-squared from this regression is distributed chi-squared with k degrees of freedom. Further, the significance of the individual coefficients on the lagged residuals can be tested using the standard t-statistic (for details on this test see Wooldridge (1996)). If the null hypothesis of dynamic completeness can not be accepted, the heteroscedasticity/seriaI-correlation (H/SC) robust standard errors should be used for inference (Wooldridge (1991)). 3.32 The Indirect Effect The estimation of equation (3.2) is carried out using pooled ordinary least squares (OLS). As with the pooled Poisson QMLE, the asymptotic properties of this estimator do not impose the strict exogeneity assumption. This allows current industry R&D expenditures to influence future values of public basic research, FDA regulation and pharmaceutical demand. 71 Robust inference requires that the standard errors be adjusted to account for the possible failure of the dynamic completeness assumption. Once again, a Lagrange multiplier statistic is used to test for serial correlation. It is the same procedure as used for the direct effect except the residuals and explanatory variables are not weighted. If serial correlation is detected, then the heteroscedasticity/serial correlation (HISC) robust standard errors will be computed following Wooldridge (1989) and used for inference. Chapter 4 The Direct Impact of Public Basic Research on Pharmaceutical Innovation 4.1 Overview This chapter explores the direct determinants of pharmaceutical innovation. It is postulated that pharmaceutical product innovation is a function of publicly funded basic research, industry R&D and FDA regulatory stringency. Previous empirical research has failed to link public basic research with pharmaceutical innovation. This link, however, is quite important. The extent to which economic agents can exploit productive external information has fundamental implications for theories of productivity and growth. Consider, for instance, that knowledge extemalities are one key to unbounded growth in endogenous growth theory. This chapter will describe how knowledge extemalities from publicly funded biomedical research impact pharmaceutical innovafion. Strong evidence is found for an economically and statistically significant impact of public research on pharmaceutical innovation (hypothesis one). Public research “capital” is intended to mimic the creation of scientific knowledge by using a cumulative stock form of measurement. The elasticity of the number of new chemical entities with respect to the stock of public basic research is found to lie in the range of 2.2 to 2.5. These point estimates are large and imply 72 73 increasing returns to scale in the pharmaceutical innovative process due to publicly funded basic research. If public basic research is used to formulate new drug concepts, then the impact of this research should come early in the drug discovery stage of the pharmaceutical innovative process (hypothesis two). In fact, the data show that public research has its most significant impact on pharmaceutical innovation seventeen years before an approved NCE. This finding implies that an average of seventeen years elapse between federal award and new product approval. Because basic research is cumulative and measured as a stock variable, this result is perhaps best interpreted as a seventeen year lag between the time basic research reaches a “maturity” point or “critical mass” and the approval of a new chemical entity. When one looks at the nature of the research that is supported by the federal government and private industry, it is clear that these two types of research are quite distinct. While pharmaceutical firms invest in basic research, by far the largest portion of their R&D investment is “applied.” The bulk of this money is spent on testing specific drugs and documenting their findings. Publicly supported basic research, on the other hand, is more diverse and general. The analysis finds that both these types of research are important in the pharmaceutical innovative process. Their distinctive contributions suggest limited substitution possibilities in the production technology (hypothesis three). Using a constant elasticity of substitution production function, the elasticity of substitution (E.) between industry R&D and public basic research is found to be 74 0.29. Since the substitution possibilities between two inputs approach the fixed proportions Leontief technology as values of E. approach zero, it can be inferred that public basic and private industry research do not easily substitute for each other in the pharmaceutical innovative process. Using the results from Grabowski and Vernon (GV) (1996) regarding the average discounted stream of revenues for a NCE, the marginal contribution of the public research stock can be given an explicit present value. The estimated marginal productivity of federally funded basic research on the number of approved new chemical entities is 0.07 per $1 million in each therapeutic class. This marginal product has a present discounted value of $13 million in real 1986 dollars at the time of introduction. In fact, the marginal contribution of public research is greater that the marginal contribution of private R&D, which has a marginal product of 0.05 per $1 million. Using the GV data and the seventeen year lag between research award and product approval, the net present value of publicly funded basic research at the time of introduction is $5582.368 million in real 1986 dollars. Further, the results hold up to robust statistical inference. Using the heteroscedasticity and serial correlation robust standard errors, the public research stock variable becomes more statistically significant. In addition to calculating the robust standard errors, the analysis allows for alternative lags describing the pharmaceutical innovative process as well as for lagged effects from FDA regulatory stringency. In both of these cases, using a finite distributed 75 lag is a robust specification since it does not restrict the coefficient values over time. 4.2 Model Specification Two empirical specifications of the KPF described by equation (3.1) are implemented. The first is the Cobb-Douglas. This formulation has been used in most studies of R&D and productivity. Besides assuming that inputs are strictly separable, the major limitation of the Cobb-Douglas functional form is that the elasticity of substitution between inputs is restricted to unity. This restriction implies that a percentage increase in the relative price of private R&D will induce the same percentage decrease in the industry’s relative quantity of private R&D input without any loss of productive output. To the extent that a dollar of public basic research buys something different than a dollar of private R&D investment, the Cobb-Douglas elasticity of substitution is probably too restrictive. To order to explore the potential substitutability between private and public research, a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production formulation is used. As its name implies, the CES requires the elasticity of substitution between inputs to be constant; however, it is not restricted to unity. In terms of the estimation, the essential difference is that an additional term, called the “substitution term,” is added as an explanatory variable. It is perhaps important to point out that the CES formulation requires a stock measure of 76 private R&D in order to avoid problems of collinearity between multiple substitution terms. The industry level Cobb-Douglas production function is: (4.1) Yit = e‘“""°(1,t)“‘ , . .. :('it-k)ak(Bit-m)m(Rit)711---»(Rit-h)7hew where i represents the medical therapeutic class, t represents time, Yit is a count of pharmaceutical innovative output, 71. and n capture the exogenous effects of time and therapeutic class on innovation, a1 - ak are the output elasticities of the industry R&D distributed lag, 'it Jit-ki B1 is the output elasticity for the stock of Public Health Service funded basic research BM“; and 71 - yh are the output elasticities for the predetermined distributed lag of FDA regulation (where h= 9), Ritw vRit-h The term, 1.1, is a random error that is assumed to have a zero mean and constant variance. The distributed lag for the pharmaceutical innovative process is specified to be length R (where k = 12 and k = 14 alternatively). The appropriate lag for PHS basic research (m) will be determined empirically. The production function is assumed to hold across therapeutic class and time. The coefficients estimates are long-run industry elasticities for each of the variables. For instance, the coefficient, B1, tells us the percentage change in the number of approved NCEs in each therapeutic class for an exogenous change in the stock of government funded basic research. The industry level results demonstrate the general importance of PHS funded research in pharmaceutical innovation. Other industry level estimates concerning the effectiveness of 77 industry R&D dollars and the industry average FDA regulatory delay will also be of interest. Since the research parameters (01,13) are not restricted to the constant returns to scale case, these estimates will shed some light on possible industry-wide increasing returns to scale stemming from the contribution of public research. The dynamics of the R&D and regulatory relationships in pharmaceutical innovation are not known with certainty and have been changing over time. In a comprehensive analysis on the cost of new drug development, DiMasi et al. (1991) find that the average time from synthesis to FDA approval is nearly twelve years for the 1979—1989 period. Moreover, in a study looking at the relationship between drug importance and time to market, Dranove and Meltzer (1994) suggest the period from patent application to FDA approval is twelve to fourteen years. Based on these studies, the analysis allows for both a twelve year and fourteen year industry lag specification. Following Grabowski et al. (1978), Wiggins (1981) and Jensen (1987), regulatory stringency is measured by the average delay between submission of a new drug application and its approval by the FDA. Both Wiggins (1981) and Jensen (1987) included their annual stringency measures lagged up to five periods prior to pharmaceutical innovation. Since it is common for pharmaceutical firms to anticipate regulatory requirements several years before submitting new drug applications, the specification of equation (4.1) allows 78 regulatory stringency to have its impact as far back as nine years prior to FDA approval.1 Chapter two suggests that PHS basic research feeds the creative conception of new therapeutic compounds with its greatest impact coming in the early stages of drug discovery. Combined with the existing studies on industry lag lengths, this implies that firms draw on the pool of available public knowledge at least thirteen years prior to the drug's approval by the FDA. Further, because research awards are used to measure the public stock of knowledge it is necessary to allow for the lag between research award and research output as well as for the lag between research completion and its utilization by industry. In the case that two years are enough time for these lags to work themselves out, the impact of basic research should occur at least fifteen years prior to an approved NCE. Using this as a starting point, the timing of the effect is explored in the next section. 4.3 The Timing of the Relationship The average timing of the impact of PHS basic research is established using both non-nested and nested regression criteria. The non-nested criteria 1 No structure is imposed on the distributed lag of FDA regulatory stringency variables. As in the case of industry R&D, this is intended to provide a better econometric control by not restricting the annual coefficients. 79 are appropriate for evaluating those regressions that include a single lag of PHS basic research. One advantage of this approach is that it avoids problems of collinearity between alternative stock variables. The nested regression criteria are applied to an additional set of regressions that include other lagged stocks as control variables. Taken together, these approaches determine the empirical timing of the impact of PHS basic research. Tables 4.1 and 4.2 present the single PHS lag regression results assuming a twelve and fourteen year industry R&D distributed lag, respectively. Each basic research stock is assumed to have a 15% depreciation rate (alternative depreciation rates are explored later in the chapter). Columns (1) through (6) show the results for the fifteenth through the twentieth lags of PHS basic research. The rows of Tables 4.1 and 4.2 show the values of the coefficient estimates and the relevant statistics for each regression. Because of space considerations not all of the regression coefficients are show in the tables. The full regression output can be seen in Appendix B. In each table, all three non-nested regression criteria , the sum of squared residuals (SSR), the coefficient of determination, and the value of the log likelihood function, indicate that PHS basic research feeds pharmaceutical innovation seventeen years prior to NCE approval. Also note that the values of these criteria are not much different for the eighteenth lag of PHS basic 80 .96. .0... o... .0 8:80:90: .25. $0 .5 s 8:85:90. «02-20. “28> ... €385 c. 2.. «80030.. 3806.2 .8. c. an 830...: __< ”202 3008 800.6 28.6 0000.6 32.6 98.8 82.30184 0000.0 030.0 «mt-0 ~83 Rt... 8&0 3300-0 89.00. 030.5 008.5 83.00. 80.09 .0800. 000 ...—800.0. ....830. ...00000. ...00000. 2.002.... .0980. 80.32 .380 00.: .83.. F. 02000. 2.5030. ..5000. .0880. ...3000. 88%.. 8:30 0...“. .803. .58... .520. ...6000. 0205. .39.: 0.533 5:0 :80... ...-.35. .500... .550. :80... .800... 80.53 88.8 303 00000 803-. 00.00 nth... 800.. 239080 03.05.30 8 a... 2 0.... 2 05 t 0.: 2 0.... 2 a... .680 02380 280 0:0 5000. 2.00.0. 3000. 080.0. 9.8.0. 2.5.0. 38.90.80 020.390 .0 .50 .8: k8; 9.00.0 68.0 85.0 2000 05.9080 000 0.2.2. .o :50 .88.... 855-. 58..-. .800... :80.-. .85.-. 80.0%-. 88.8 800.2- 0. 6.:- ~000.2- 23.:- 00§07 008.0. .5380 0 0 v 0 N 0 80.50 s is; 88300 0002 a .500 “300...; 2880100 00-. 53.0.... 80> N. 5.; 8.38m gaom 03002-002 6000 $03 30.00001 0.000 01a - ...v 0.000. 81 .96. 0... 9.. .0 8:80.090.- ..96. 0.0 o... .0 8080.00.0- 000..0.0. .28.. ... 0.9.8... c. 0.0 80000.9. 00205.2 .00. c. 2.. 8.0009 ..< 0.02 000000 0000. .0 0.00. .0 0000. .0 80.. .0 0.0000 080.2... 03 0020 01-00 02-00 000.0 0.000 00000 02300-0 000.0. 000000. 000000. 0. .000. 0000.00. 0000.00. 000 .0800. 2.80.0.0. ...0000. 2.000... 2.0.00.0. ...-08.... 0000....-. .880 00... .00.... .. .00000. ...0000. 2.0000... ... .020. ..00000. 000050.. .380 ...... .0000... .000... .3000. .0080. .00.0... .0000... 000080.. ...-.0 ..000... .0000... .0000... .0000... .0000... .000... 000080.. 88.00 300.. 0.00.0 8000 00000 0.00.. .00... 50.9080 00.05000 00 0.... 0. 0.3 0. 00.. 0. 0.3 0. 0.... 0. 0.... .8... 02280 0.20 0:0 .800- 00000. 00000- 0000? 0.000. 0000.? 0.8.0.080 00.0.0000 .0 .50 .00... 0.000 00000 E00 00000 .0000 0.8.0.080 000 0.80... .0 200 .0000. .-. .0000.-. 5.0..-. .0000.-. .0000.-. .200.-. 0.2.0.0.. 080.00 0000.0.- k. ..0.. 0000....- 800.0.. 00000.- 0.....0- .0880 0 0 0 0 0 . 00.030 a 0.08.3 gnaw 0002 .0 .500 0.000; 0.008.000 00-. .5800. .8> 0. 5.3 2.080 8.08.000 0808-82 .000 $0.. 09880 0.80 0:0 - 0 0 0.0... 82 research. Further, the timing of the basic research contribution is consistent across both industry lag specifications, either the twelve year or fourteen year. Tables 4.3 and 4.4 present the alternative PHS stock regression results. Each table shows two alternative regressions in which the seventeenth lag of PHS basic research is set against alternative lags. The first regression includes the twelfth, seventeenth, and twenty-second lags. The second regression expands the range to ninth, seventeenth, and twenty-fifth lags. In each of these specifications only the seventeenth lag of PHS basic research falls within the range hypothesized in chapter two. Although the collinearity of these stock variables lowers the precision of the estimates, the seventeenth lag stands out as the relevant timing. Both the generalized linear model (GLM) and fully robust standard errors show statistical significance at conventional levels. Consequently, both regression approaches support the timing hypothesis outlined in chapter two. Moreover, the results are consistent with previous studies on the lag in pharmaceutical innovation (see DiMasi et al. (1991) and Dranove and Meltzer(1994)). Since an F-test found that the thirteenth and fourteenth lags of industry R&D do not add explanatory value to the equaiton, the remainder of the discussion will focus on the twelve year industry lag results shown in Table 4.1. 83 ._o>o_ x; 05 «a 8:85:99. ..26. {on 2: E 8:35:99. 33.03? H83> .a 29.35 5 2a 8:383 0:05.52 duo. a. 2a 85%? .< ”202 82.8 m r38 3239.: 8.4 3:6 326 uoaaamé 83.3 88¢? mwm 5.8. 2 L883 883. .982 Luzon 8803 0363.. $33. as... 53.2 ..an 5. .582 .882 L38. 2 85.3 80.53.. 2.6 3R0... .52.. a fixed. .38.... .88. z .833 03.22 88.8 8.3 .53 «~30 8:8 v83 «83. 220580 8555 an 2.. t a... o 8.. a a... t 9.. «P 8.. goo.» =288¢ 23m 9: 80¢. 82¢- 38.0580 bassoon .0 25 3.3.6 53 25.0580 Sm £32. a .56 NE... E 394.. Z 083%.“ 88.8 58.2- 85.2- 2588 N F 88% a 03%.; Boson—ow 502 .o ano 65%; E3530 8.. 5.8... 30> m. 5.; 238m 538.com 8.82 28 gm: 558cm comm wxa - 3 22¢ .26. ...; as a 858.com: .65. 3m 9.. «a 8:85:99 39.39 65; ... 89.85 5 2a 83.83 0.63.5.3 .80. c. 05 3.3.3.. .4. ”202 8m :8 2.: .3 82.23.34 ES 3:... 853m-.. 338. 5.58. «mm .832 2.532 .832 89.2 ...882 882..-. 88%.. .253. 2...“. 5.2.2 .85.. z .882 .852 ...:fi. 2 .88..-. 03%.. 2.6 .88.... .88. a .332 .832 :3... 2 HBO... 8%.». 838 8.3 88a 88... 8:3 Show 2%.... 220580 Begum on 3.. t a... a on. a 2.. t a... 3 a... .8.» 5288: 2.8 mza 33.... :5... 25.0580 €5.33. .0 55 ~33 .38... 95.0580 9E £32. a saw .88.... .82..-. 8%.. Samoa 88.2- 32.2. 232.8 m . 888m 3 22...; 2.333 £02 .0 ano 6.3:; Eoucaoo 9.. ESE. as. 3 5.; 258m 5.829.. 2.82 .30 ....m 5 5.88m ovum wIa - 3 2%» 4.4 The Magnitude of the Public Research Impact Given the fact that PHS funded research is an intermediate input into an innovative process that is subject to long lags, it is not surprising that its economic impact has been hotly debated in policy circles. Looking at the estimated coefficients in columns (3) and (4) of Table 4.1, the economic significance of PHS basic research as a determinant of pharmaceutical innovation becomes clear. An estimated constant elasticity ranging between 2.2 and 2.5 implies a 10% increase in the stock of PHS basic research will, on average, lead to a 22% to 25% increase in the number of approved NCEs in each of the seven therapeutic classes. The following two examples provide a sense of the important impact of PHS basic research on pharmaceutical innovation. First, consider the impact of a 10% increase in the basic research stock in 1976 on the number of approved NCEs in 1993. In 1976 the PHS granted $705 million in awards for basic research across all classes. This is approximately 26% of all PHS extramural awards given in that year. A 10% increase in the stock of basic research available in 1976 would have required an additional $216 million—an 8% reallocation of the total value of PHS awards to basic research. The effect, on average, would have been five additional therapeutic compounds in each class in 1993. It should be noted that this impact will continue to feed pharmaceutical innovation beyond 1993. 85 86 Unlike overall federal basic research, PHS funding of basic research relevant to the pharmaceutical industry has not experienced a dramatic decline in real annual growth. This contrast in funding trends allows us to ask what pharmaceutical innovation would have been had PHS basic research followed the overall trend. The counter factual experiment illustrates both the importance of federally funded basic research in pharmaceutical innovation as well as the potential impact of changes in the real growth rate of basic research funding. Using the estimated model, Figure 4.1 shows the impact of imposing a slower growth rate in PHS basic research funding on pharmaceutical innovation. The solid line represents the observed (and predicted) number of approved NCEs in the sample period 1978-1994. The dotted line represents the predicted number of NCEs with an imposed 0.6% decline in the real growth rate of PHS basic research. Holding all else constant, this decline leads to a drop in the average number of approved NCEs from 19 to 11. Clearly, evidence from the pharmaceutical industry suggests that a decline in the growth rate of federal basic research funds will lead to a significant drop in measured innovation. 4.5 The Statistical Significance of Public Research The tests for statistical significance involve alternative assumptions on the conditional variance of NCEs as well as accounting for potential serial correlation in the implied disturbances. Until recently, the most common test for 87 .5266 $8.8 £380 @595“. 2058mm 23m Ema 532w 5.2, 293 8.66:... _8_.:mom§mcn. - _..v 8:9... 93> QQQQQQQQQQQQQQQQQ aces/020002..@ovcesooaeezeooo(o( 11il ill... Tl+ .. .1..i!-.|--rll+il+llT|.iiTl..-ilT ._ . c nmoz .5803. 38.3.... I l l mwoz case}. octomnOIIl genome”. 28m 38.8... c. :32... 833 ...? £30.. congoccT . .l . . SBON penciddv JO tunog .302 3353‘. «.33 5230:... V1. -- 88 statistical significance in count data models assumed the Poisson nominal variance property in which the mean and variance are restricted to equality. Under this assumption, which is shown in column (3) of Table 4.1, the seventeenth lag of PHS basic research has a positive coefficient with a t-statistic equal to 2.02 implying a p-value < 0.025 (one-sided alternative). The weakness of this assumption is that it rarely holds in empirical applications and, consequently, can lead to spuriously high levels of significance. The next two assumptions generalize the Poisson property. The GLM assumption allows a proportional relationship between the mean and the variance. Since the conditional distribution of NCEs is characterized by underdispersion, estimated c2 < 1, the variance is less than the mean. Accounting for the underdispersion in the conditional distribution of NCEs leads to a smaller standard error. So, PHS basic research has a t-statistic equal to 2.25 implying a p-value < 0.025. The underdispersion finding is consistent with previous research on pharmaceutical innovation. In particular, Thomas (1990) also found underdispersion in his analysis of NCEs and pharmaceutical regulation. Finally, the fully robust standard error does not impose any restriction on the conditional variance of NCEs. The fully robust t-statistic is equal to 3.56 implying a very small p-value, less than 0.0001. Consequently, regardless of which assumption on the conditional variance of NCEs one feels is most appropriate, PHS basic research is strongly statistically significant. 89 To be completely robust, it is necessary to account for the time dimension of the data.2 A Lagrange Multiplier test is used to detect serial correlation in the implied disturbances. Both the magnitude and significance of the serial correlation indicator variables show that negative serial correlation is present in the model. The LM statistic for the regression is (T-4) * (uncentered R-Squared) = 35.19. Using the chi-squared distribution with four degrees of freedom, the null hypothesis of no serial correlation is rejected at a 5% level. Based on this finding, the heteroskedasticity-serial correlation (HISC) robust standard error is calculated accounting for up to fourth order serial correlation. The adjustment for serial correlation reduces the standard error to 0.2508. As seen in column (3) of Table 4.1, the resulting t-statistic on PHS basic research is 8.95 showing a high statistical significance. 4.6 Alternative Depreciation Rates for Public Research In general, the impact of PHS basic research on pharmaceutical innovation is robust to the assumed depreciation rate of knowledge capital. Up to this point the empirical analysis has assumed a 15% depreciation rate of PHS basic research. Although this is the depreciation rate used Hall et al. (1988), if the effect of federally funded basic research is important, we would expect a 2 Adjusting the standard errors for serial correlation ex post has the advantage of not imposing auxiliary assumptions on the model. Using a FGLS AR(1) or higher order model would have introduced common factor restrictions into the statistical model. See Wooldridge (1991) for further discussion. 90 change in the depreciation rate to only affect the magnitude of the effect and not its timing or statistical significance. The magnitude of the impact will depend on the size of the effective “knowledge stock.” To evaluate the sensitivity of the timing, magnitude, and significance of the PHS basic research results to the assumed depreciation rate, the non-nested regression analysis is repeated using both a 10% and a 20% depreciation rate for the basic research stock. .The results of the sensitivity analysis can be seen in Tables 4.5 and 4.6. As before, the non-nested criteria point to the seventeenth and eighteenth lags as the relevant timing of the effect. The pattern of statistical significance remains unchanged. The magnitude of the effect, however, does change slightly when alternative depreciation rates are used. Under the 10% rate, the estimated impact is greatest with a coefficient of 2.6 as opposed to a coefficient of 2.0 under a 20% depreciation rate. The pattern implies a slightly smaller impact when the effective stock of basic research “knowledge capital” decays rapidly. 4.7 The Industry Elasticity and Net Present Value of Public Research The estimated elasticity of industry R&D can be seen in row 3 of Tables 4.1 and 4.2. Focusing on seventeenth lag of basic research in column (3), it can be seen that the magnitude of the cumulative effect of pharmaceutical R&D does not change dramatically between the two lag specifications. Under the twelve year specification, industry R&D has an elasticity estimate of 0.69 while, .26. .... o... .- 83.5w: .26. ...... o... .a 8:82:98. .838. ”88> ... 8.8... c. 2.. 8.85.... 8885.2 68. ... a. 83...? ..< 5.02 91 88.8 .818 88. ... 88.8 «new. a 88.8 82.9... .5 82.... «at... 8k... «83 8t... 2t... 8.38-.. 88.8. 9.5.8. $8.8. 88.8. 28.5 88.8. «8. L882 ...582 ...882 ...882 :88... ...882 8859. .88.. cm... :8... s ..832 3.882 Lot-n2 ...882 .2822 88.8-. .88”. ...... .83... ...-NE... .582 .882 ...83. Sam... 88...... ...-.0 .38... 28:... ...-88... ...-.382 .88. z .883. 88s.... 88...... 88.. 89... 82..“ 83a 58.. 88.. Egg-:80 8.23 8 a... 2 a... 2 ...: t a... . 2 a... 2 a... ...-.8» ‘22.... 2.8 2: 89.... 88.... 8:8. 88.... 88.9 88...- 839880 82.38.. .o 58 «SN. .8... 88... $2... 8:... «8:... £58.80 2:. .382. .o 58 .85..-. .82..-. .88..-. .83..-. .98..-. .85.-. 883... 88.9". 92.9- 898.- «837 88.:- §..«.. 88....- .588 o n v n u . 888 a 28...; £883 omoz .0 .58 5.8.; E8880 ...... .326... as. m. a. 3.3.... 5.828.. 8.82.82 8.88m 0.8m 9.... .- 83888 .8. - m... 038 .26. .... 6:. ... 8:8...85: .26. .8 o... .a 8:8...:...w. v8.8... .28.. ... 26.8... :. e... 8.6.5.... 883.2 .68. :. 2.. 8.8:? ..< 682 92 88.8 8%.... .8... ... 88.... .895 8...... 82.3% v.8... 8.... .8... 8.... ...... 8.... 8.26m-.. 8... .n. 88.8. ..88. 29.8. .898. 88.8. «mm 2.8.88. ...888. ..........m. ...88... 2.8:... 2.88... 88...... .263. om... .88. .. ..888. 2.68.8. :28... 2.8.88. ...83... 88.6.. .88.. 2...“. .... .... .. .....8. .. ...... . .8. .. 8.8.8. .88. .. .88. .. 9.8.6.. 2.0 .88... .68.... .88... 8.8... .88.... .88... 88....-. 88.8 88.. 8.... {-8.8 88.8 8.0. 1..... 26.8.80 3.2.3 8 ...... a. a... .. ...... .. 2.. o. a... a. a... .8.» 2288.. 28m ...... 8.8. 88.9 8.3- 68.? 8...? 8...... 8:38.80 3853...... .o :5».- .8... ..8... 8m... 88... 88... 68... 3:28.80 Sm E52. .0 saw .88..-. ..8...-. .38..-. .88..-. .88. .-. .82..-. 8886-. 58.6.. 88.... .83.- «83.. 8887 88...- B8..- .588 o n v a a . 0.6.6.... a 6.8:; 68.33 802 .258 ”2......28288 on. .532. 56> a. a. 8.3:. 8.68.8... 38.82 5.88.. 0.8m mxa .- 886280 .88 - o... 6...... 93 under the fourteen year lag, the elasticity is 0.72. These estimates are similar to ' the findings of Thomas (1990) whose elasticity estimate is 0.66. The results indicate that the marginal contribution of PHS funded basic research (MP = 0.067 per $1 million) is larger than the marginal contribution of industry R&D (MP = 0.046 per $1 million) leading to approved NCEs. This makes sense given the different nature of public basic research and industry R&D. Whereas public research expands fundamental knowledge about disease processes, the bulk of industry R&D effort is devoted to animal and human testing of specific compounds for safety and efficacy. Basic research has broader applicability and may contribute to the discovery and development of many therapeutic compounds. An alternative method for evaluating the relative merit of our national investment in basic biomedical research is to calculate the net present value (NPV) of this investment. A recent study by Grabowski and Vernon (1996) uses a sample of new chemical entities and a product life cycle model to estimate the present value of cash flows for an average NCE. Their present value stream of cash flows for an average NCE is $193.1896 million in real 1986 dollars. If we take an initial 10% increase in the stock of PHS basic research, say in 1976, then our investment in basic research will produce an average of five approved NCEs in each therapeutic class by 1993. Across all classes, this gives a total NPV of cash flows of $6761.636 million [(5 NCEs) * (7 classes) *(193.1896 cash flow per NCE)] at the time of drug introduction. To calculate the NPV, we capitalize our initial investment of $216 million at 105% (this is the GV (1996) 94 cost of capital) and subtract this from the present value of cash flows. Doing this calculation indicates that our public investment in basic research has a positive NPV of $5582.368 million in real 1986 dollars at the time of introduction. 4.8 Substitution Possibilities, Returns to Scale, and FDA Regulation Given that the marginal productivity of public research is greater than that of private R&D, one might suggest that public funding should be substituted for private funding in order to increase the number of new therapeutic compounds available to fight disease. This suggestion is overly simplistic. A closer look at the nature of the research funded with federal monies and the research funded with private industry monies reveals that these separate funding agents are “buying” different types of research. Most obviously, public basic research does not include the uncertain and expensive animal and human testing for safety and efficacy that must be completed to obtain FDA approval. In order to investigate the potential substitutability between publicly funded basic research and private industry R&D, a substitution parameter is introduced into the model based on the CES production function described by Kmenta (1967). In this extension of the model, industry R&D is specified as a stock variable using the methodology established by Thomas (1990). The results of this regression appear in Table 4.7. The estimated elasticity of substitution (E5) of industry R&D for public basic research is 0.29. Since this value is near zero, 95 Table 4.7 - CES Production Function Estimation Dependent Variable: Count of NCEs Ecmation Variable or Statistic 1 Constant -12.5714 Poisson t-statistic {-1.7121] Industry R&D Stock Coefficient 0.3773 Poisson t-statistic [0.625] GLM t-statistic [0.7238] Fully Robust t-statistic [42677]“ "Substitution" Term: (ln l/B)"2 -0.3996 Poisson t-statistic {-1.0344] GLM t-statistic [-1 . 1 979] Fully Robust t-statistic [-2.1903]‘ Sum of Regulatory Coefficients -0.4941 PHS Basic Research Stock (15% dep.) Lag 17 Estimated Coefficient 2.1769 Poisson t-statistic [20306]" GLM t—statistic [21852]" Fully Robust t-statistic [42099]“ SSR 157.3997 R-Squared 0.7209 Log Likelihood 85.6068 Elasticity of Substitution 0.2869 Scale Parameter 2.5542 Note: All variables are in logs. Asymptotic t-statistics are in brackets [1 Years: 1978-1994 'Significance at the 5% level. “Significance at the 1% level. 96 public basic and private industry R&D are substitutable, however, they are poor substitutes. In the CES model, the elasticity of substitution can vary between 0 and so. When Es —> 0, the isoquants become L shaped indicating a fixed proportions Leontief technology. The result implies that pharmaceutical technology is characterized by limited substitution possibilities between private R&D and public basic research. A 1% increase in the relative price of private R&D investment, holding output constant, will only allow a 0.29% decease in the relative use of private R&D (its factor share). And, since the relationship is symmetric, a 1% increase in the relative price of public basic research, holding output constant, will only allow a 0.29% decrease in the industry’s relative use of this research. This finding is consistent with the development of our national research enterprise following World War II. Our national commitment to financing an expanding institutional foundation producing basic research, largely through universities, has created a profitable and productive opportunity for the pharmaceutical industry to specialize in more applied research. One may argue that what has evolved is more or less an institutional division of labor. Both the Cobb-Douglas and CES estimation results indicate strong increasing returns to scale in the discovery and development of approved new chemical entities. Under the twelve year industry distributed lag, the sum of the research coefficients (a, B) is 2.89, while the scale parameter in the CES regression is 2.55. Without the contribution of PHS basic research, the estimates indicate that pharmaceutical innovation is characterized by decreasing returns to scale. Most previous studies, including Henderson and Cockbum 97 (1996), do not find evidence of increasing returns to scale in pharmaceutical innovation in the post-1978 sample period. However, it is important to keep in mind that previous studies have not included a measure of basic biomedical research. If fact, it is the contribution of this research that leads to industry increasing returns to scale. The cumulative effect of FDA regulatory stringency can be seen in row 4 of Tables 4.1 and 4.2. Regardless of the industry lag specified, the cumulative elasticity is -0.59. In the CES estimation, the elasticity has a value of -0.49. Although there are no other estimates of FDA regulation for the sample period used in this study, the estimate is slightly lower than the estimate reported by Grabowski el al. (1978) in their study of the regulatory impact of the Kefauver- Harris Amendments of 1962. FDA regulation appears to have a fairly strong negative impact on pharmaceutical innovation. 4.9 Conclusion Strong evidence is found for an economically and statistically significant impact of public research on pharmaceutical innovation (hypothesis one). The elasticity of the number of new chemical entities with respect to the stock of public basic research “capital” is found to lie in the range of 2.2 to 2.5. These point estimates are large and imply increasing returns to scale in the pharmaceutical innovative process due to publicly funded basic research. 98 The chapter finds that public research has its most significant impact on pharmaceutical innovation seventeen years before an approved NCE. This is consistent with the idea that pharmaceutical scientists monitor public research and use public research results in drug discovery. It is the drug concept stage of the pharmaceutical innovative process in which publicly funded basic research has its impact (hypothesis two). This result is perhaps best interpreted as a seventeen year lag between the time basic research reaches a “maturity" point or “critical mass” and the approval of a new chemical entity. Publicly funded basic research and the bulk of industry investment are very different in their objectives and results. Public basic research is typically more diverse and general while private industry R&D tends to be directed at testing specific drugs and documenting their findings. Each type of research is important in the pharmaceutical innovative process. Their distinctive contributions imply limited substitution possibilities in the production technology. The estimated elasticity of substitution (E) of 0.29 supports this hypothesis. it is found that the marginal productivity of federally funded basic research is 0.07 per $1 million in each therapeutic class. A $7 million investment in public basic research produces, after a lag of seventeen years, a present discounted value of $91 million in real 1986 dollars at the time of drug introduction. Further, publicly funded basic research has a large net present value. The NPV equals $5582.368 in real 1986 dollars at the time of introduction. The results hold up to robust statistical inference. As assumptions regarding the conditional variance of NCEs are relaxed, the estimated impact 99 becomes more significant. The heteroscedasticity and serial correlation robust asymptotic t—statistic is 8.96. Further, the impact is robust to alternative industry lag specifications. A twelve year innovative lag is preferred by the data. Finally, the PHS impact is robust to variation in FDA regulatory stringency. This effect was allowed to reach as far back as nine years prior to FDA approval. CHAPTER 5 The Indirect Impact of Public Basic Research on Pharmaceutical Innovation: Investment in Response to Research Opportunities 5.1 Overview This chapter explores the indirect impact of public basic research and FDA regulatory stringency on pharmaceutical innovation. Each of these factors indirectly impacts the number approved new chemical entities by influencing the level of industry R&D investment. Hypothesis four, developed in chapter two, postulates that public funding of basic biomedical research facilitates advances in public scientific understanding and thereby creates research opportunities for new drug discovery. As new avenues to therapeutic outcomes emerge, private industry attempts to exploit these opportunities by investing in research and development. The induced private R&D investment makes some contribution to the successful introduction of new therapeutic compounds. This is the indirect effect of public basic research on pharmaceutical innovation. Similar to public funding of basic research, FDA regulatory stringency indirectly impacts pharmaceutical innovation by influencing the level of industry R&D investment. In this case, however, one would expect that increases in regulatory stringency reduce industry research and development investment. Empirical support for this hypothesis was provided by Wiggins (1979, 1983). 100 101 Because of the parallel approach taken here, it is expected that increases in regulatory delay lower industry R&D investment. Both analyses use the same methodology to construct the regulatory stringency proxy variable and use the same source for industry research and development data. This similarity provides an opportunity to compare results and test the robustness of Wiggins’ analysis. Direct comparisons with Wiggins (1983) appears in section 5.5 of the chapter. The central objective of this chapter is to empirically describe the timing, magnitude, and significance of the indirect impact of public research on pharmaceutical innovation. Of the previous research, no study has linked publicly funded research with pharmaceutical innovation. Ward and Dranove (1995) explore the inducement effect of NIH obligations on pharmaceutical investment but stop short of linking this with innovation. Henderson and Cockbum (1996) and Grabowski and Vernon (1981) have used “research program” and firm level data to look at the determinants of pharmaceutical R&D investment without including any measures of public research. As regards FDA regulation, Wiggins (1979) was the first to use therapeutic class distinctions to show that FDA regulatory stringency depressed pharmaceutical investment and innovation. Ward and Dranove (1995), on the other hand, use a somewhat different approach and find that “expected” approval delays increase pharmaceutical R&D investment. This chapter advances our understanding of the determinants of pharmaceutical industry investment and the indirect contribution of public 102 biomedical knowledge to pharmaceutical innovation. Whereas previous analyses have treated public research investment in a broad and somewhat simplistic fashion, this analysis is based on detailed public research awards data that have been carefully classified into meaningful therapeutic categories for each year between 1955 and 1985. Additionally, the contribution of biomedical knowledge is measured as a capitalized stock. This is intended to mimic the cumulative Ieaming process that characterizes the advancement of scientific research. Both of these aspects improve the empirical results by reducing the measurement error and matching limitations found in previous research. The chapter finds that the elasticity of industry R&D investment with respect to the stock of publicly funded basic research lies in the range of 0.42 to 0.46. Although publicly funded research begins to stimulate industry investment as early as three years following award, the data reveal that its effect is statistically dominant in the seventh year following research award. Using the estimated marginal effect of industry R&D on approved NCEs from chapter four, a $1 million increase in the PHS research stock produces a marginal physical product of 0.01 approved NCEs in each of the seven therapeutic classes. This amounts to a total increase in pharmaceutical innovation of 0.07 additional approved NCEs (across all classes). If this increase in innovative output earns the average discounted revenue, then a discounted present value of $10.3 million in additional revenue will be produced at the time of introduction. As regards FDA regulatory stringency, the point estimates are statistically insignificant and small in magnitude. These elasticities, one for the current year 103 through the fourth lag of regulatory stringency, were not found to be statistically different from zero either individually or jointly. Taken literally, this implies that a marginal increase in FDA approval delay time does not affect the level of industry R&D. Although this may be true, collinearity among the included stringency variables is one cause of the imprecise estimates. If we put any faith in the estimated coefficients, then the cumulative impact of FDA regulatory stringency has an overall elasticity value of -0.1023. The chapter contains several other ancillary results. Perhaps the most interesting of these pertains to industry sales. With an estimated elasticity of 0.24, a 1% increase in pharmaceutical sales in 1985 would have increased industry investment by $7.1 million in that year. Using the estimated impact of industry investment on the production of NCEs found in chapter four, this increase produces 0.08 new therapeutic compounds across all classes after twelve years. Again, if these marginal NCEs each earn the average discounted revenue, then this increase in sales will bring fourth nearly $14.8 million in new revenues at the time of introduction. It is also found that industry R&D investment increases with disease incidence and falls with disease “severity.” A 1% increase in disease incidence in the forty-five to sixty-four year old age group leads to an 0.4% increase in industry investment. The estimated effect of disease “severity,” which is measured as the number of hospital days, is negative and significant. Thus, longer hospital stays are associated with lower pharmaceutical investment. 104 The last section of the chapter presents some exploratory analysis regarding the potential simultaneity bias between publicly funded research and private industry R&D investment. As discussed in chapter three, this is the “scientific opportunity” problem. It arises when research funding agents respond to the same “scientific break-through“ information when making their funding decisions and thereby induce a correlation that is not a spillover of knowledge. Using instruments for public research implied by the Ward and Dranove (1995) analysis, no evidence is found that supports an endogeneity bias due to scientific opportunity. The intended instruments, however, are poorly correlated with public funding of basic research. This makes the endogeneity test uninformative as to the presence of a scientific opportunity problem. Nevertheless, scientific opportunity is unlikely to affect lagged public funding. The analysis finds that the relevant public and private funding decisions are separated by a seven year period. In order for scientific opportunity to be causing a simultaneity bias, the relevant scientific opportunities would need to remain constant over the seven year period. This seems unlikely. 5.2 Model Specification Based on previous research as well as interviews with industry marketing personnel, this section follows the net present value (NPV) methodology for modeling pharmaceutical R&D investment decisions. This method is consistent with the interview responses given to Wiggins (1979) and used in his analysis. 105 It is also the approach taken by Grabowski and Vernon (1981) in their firm level analysis of the determinants of pharmaceutical R&D investment. The basic NPV relation is shown in equation (5.1). The calculated NPV is the difference between a project’s discounted present value stream of expected revenue and its the discounted present value stream of expected costs. If the NPV is positive, then it is profitable to invest in the R&D project. If the NPV is less than or equal to zero, then it is not profitable to invest. (5.1) NPV = PV[expected revenues] - PV[expected costs] To make projects comparable, the discounted present value of cash flows for revenues and costs are calculated using a “discount factor" that adjusts for the time value of money and for risk. Alternatively, the internal rate of return for a proposed R&D project can be calculated. This return is the value of the discount rate that equates the present value of expected revenues and expected costs. Comparing the calculated internal rates of return to the opportunity cost of capital for any project is one way of making an R&D investment decision.1 If the firm calculates the internal rate of return for all projects and ranks them in descending order, then they can fund projects down to the point where the return on the marginal project just equals the cost of capital. Notice that this assumes pharmaceutical firms are not liquidity constrained. 1 The opportunity cost of capital is the expected rate of return to investors offered by all other investments of similar risk. 106 It is useful to image a downward sloping “marginal return to investment” schedule plotted with the rate of return on the vertical axis and the level of investment on the horizontal axis. Given the distribution of returns, the downward slope of the curve reflects that R&D investment increases as additional R&D projects are funded. Along this curve, all variables influencing the rate of return on new chemical entities are held constant. Because the opportunity cost of capital is assumed to be exogenous, it is represented by a horizontal line emanating from the vertical axis and extending across all levels of investment. The equilibrium level of investment is determined by the intersection of the “marginal return” schedule and the “opportunity cost of capital” schedule. The empirical analysis will be done on an industry level using the observed level of investment in each medical therapeutic class. It is postulated that public basic research, FDA regulatory stringency, and demand factors influence the rate of return and shift the marginal return schedule for each therapeutic class. Macro changes that shift the opportunity cost of capital schedule are modeled using yearly time dummy variables. Allowing each year to have its own intercept is the most general way to account for variation over time due to inflation, industry shocks and other unobserved “macro” changes. Therapeutic class dummies are included to account for the fixed differences in technological opportunity across medical classes. Depending on the distribution of research investment and scientific skill, one class may feed into drug 107 discovery more easily than another. The structural investment equation is as follows: (5.2) In = (Bitm)"‘(Rit)",... ,(Rit_h)’"(Salesit)°‘(lncit)°2(Sevit)°3e‘”""°e°° where i represents the medical therapeutic class, t represents time. 'it is the level of industry research and development investment; [31 is the long-run investment elasticity with respect to the lagged stock of PHS funded basic biomedical research, Bit-m ; y1-yh are the investment elasticities with respect to the distributed lag of regulatory stringency, Rit - RM, (length h = 4); 01-03 are the elasticities of investment with respect to industry sales, U.S. disease incidence and severity, respectively. The M (one for each year) are the semi- elasticities capturing changes in the opportunity cost of capital while the ni correspond to each therapeutic class. The term, It. is a random disturbance with mean zero and constant variance. The lag, m, characterizing the stock of PHS basic research will be determined empirically. It is postulated that increases in the stock of public basic research knowledge, BM”, lead to increases in the level of pharmaceutical investment. In the present framework, this effect works by increasing the rate of return for all projects in a given therapeutic class. Although research opportunities may affect the rate of return through alternative mechanisms, it is likely that the effect of public research is some combination of lower costs and a higher the probability 108 of success. Either by lowering expected costs or increasing the expected payoff to private R&D, public research increases the rate of return. This implies [31 > 0. It was noted above that increases in FDA regulatory stringency are expected to lower pharmaceutical R&D investment, *1" < 0. FDA regulation can lower the rate of return through two mechanisms. First, changes in regulatory stringency may increase the risk of FDA approval in a therapeutic class. In our framework, an increase in the risk of approval implies a lower probability of approval. With a lower probability of approval, fewer R&D projects will be profitable because the expected revenue stream will be lower. If fewer projects are pursued, then investment will be lower. The second mechanism works through the costs of approval and holds the risk of approval constant. In this case, an increase in the expected stream of costs associated with getting an FDA approved drug lowers the rate of return to all projects. Assuming the opportunity cost of capital remains constant, fewer projects will be pursued and R&D investment will be lower. In a multi-period setting, FDA product quality regulation may either increase or decrease pharmaceutical research investment. To the extent that increases in regulatory stringency require more testing and documentation, the cost of those compounds already in the pipeline will increase, yj > 0. However, if firms are able to adjust their portfolios of research investment, then increased regulatory stringency would reduce the number of profitable candidate compounds. Fewer profitable compounds, in turn, lead to reduced spending as 109 these potential new therapies are not pursued, yj < 0. It is this later effect that Wiggins (1983) found to be dominant between 1971 and 1976. However, Ward and Dranove (1995) find the former effect to be dominant. Industry sales and measures of US. disease incidence and severity are included in the structural equation to represent the influence of expected demand on the pharmaceutical investment decision. Increases in industry sales are expected to increase the level of pharmaceutical investment, 01 > 0. This effect can work through two alternative channels. First, sales represent an important source of funds for financing R&D projects. To the extent that pharmaceutical firms are liquidity constrained, greater sales allow firms to fund additional projects and increase their level of R&D investment. It should be noted, however, that the rate of return framework used here assumes that firms are not liquidity constrained. The second channel works through the market information provided by drug sales. Here, the level of sales acts as an indicator of market size and the potential for future sales. To the extent that observed sales in a therapeutic class affect the forecasted revenue stream for projects in that therapeutic class, sales will influence the level of R&D investment. It is expected that greater sales signals increasing market demand. This, in turn, shifts the marginal return schedule up and stimulates investment. This analysis includes two additional measures of expected demand, disease incidence and “severity” for the civilian non-institutionalized US. population. Based on the first listed diagnosis on the hospital discharge sheet, the total number of discharges are summed across disease category into 110 therapeutic classes by year and age group. Disease “severity,” which is measured as the total number of nights in the hospital, is constructed using the same methodology. For each variable, four age groupings are used: 0-14 years, 15-44 years, 45-64 years, and 65 and older. It is expected that increases in disease incidence and severity lead to greater demand for therapeutic compounds. As demand increases, the expected revenue streams are increased and the return to all projects in that therapeutic class shift up. Holding all else constant, industry R&D investment will increase, 0j > 0. 5.3 Functional Form Previous studies of pharmaceutical investment and regulation have used either the linear model (Wiggins (1979, 1983), Grabowski and Vernon (1981), Jensen (1987), Henderson and Cockburn ( 1996)) or the log-log functional form (Ward and Dranove (1995)). In all cases, the authors did not claim that their choice of functional form was based on a statistical test. In this analysis, however, two alternative econometric tests were used to determine the statistically preferred functional form. The first, developed by Davidson and MacKinnon (1981) (DM), is referred to as the P5 test. The second test was developed by Wooldridge (1991) and is robust to heteroscedasticity and serial correlation. The results of all tests indicate that the log-log specification is preferred. Two DM tests were performed. The first test takes the linear model as the null 111 hypothesis and involves evaluating the statistical significance of a nested indicator variable (the indicator is calculated as the difference between predicted values of the alternative models). With the linear model as the null, the indicator variable has a asymptotic t-statistic of 6.0879 (p-value < 0.0005). Thus, the null linear hypothesis is rejected in favor of the alternative log-log hypothesis. In the second DM test, the log-log model served as the null hypothesis. In this case, the indicator was statistically insignificant with a t-statistic of -1.3127. Consequently, the log-log null hypothesis is not rejected. The limitation of the DM test is that it assumes a correctly specified conditional variance. The test proposed by Wooldridge (1991), however, is robust to conditional variance mis-specification, including both heteroscedasticity and serial correlation.2 He proposes a Lagrange Multiplier test which produces a chi-squared statistic under the null hypothesis. Taking the log-log model as the null hypothesis, the value of the test statistic is 0071. This is less than the chi-squared critical value at a 1% significance level and one degree of freedom. Thus, the robust test fails the reject the null log-log hypothesis. 2 To be completely precise, the correspondence between the linear and log- linear models requires the additional assumption that E(l|X) is proportional to exp(E[log(l)|x]). This, however, is not restrictive and is usually assumed implicitly. 5.4 The Regression Results and Discussion Table 5.1 presents the regression results for equation (5.2) using alternative lags of the PHS basic research stock. The leftmost column lists the variables and the relevant statistics while columns (1) through (9) of the table show the results for the alternative lags of public research. Notice that the heteroscedasticity (Hetero) and the heteroscedasticity/serial correlation robust (HISC) standard errors have been calculated for the PHS basic research variable following Wooldridge (1989). The HISC standard errors were calculated accounting for up to 1st order serial correlation. It should be noted that this is not the same as using a feasible generalized least-squares (FGLS) procedure with an AR(1) model for the errors. Unlike F GLS, the procedure used here does not impose any common factor restrictions on the model (see Wooldridge (1991) for further details). 5.41 Timing of the Relationship In order to describe the magnitude and significance of the indirect impact of public research, the timing of its relationship with pharmaceutical investment must be considered. This is important because there is a time lag between the financial award to researchers and when this research becomes available to the broader research community. The empirical identification of the appropriate lag 112 113 .92 .9 2.. ... 8:85:29: .26. :8 o... s 8:85:29. .26. $9 2.. ... 8:82:99 89.4an n800> ... 82:2: :. a: 8.2.8-. 2.0192 .30. c. 8: 332.9. __< ”:82 8. 8. 8. 8. 8. 8. 8. 8. 8. 82583983232 83.: 93.: 93.: 83.: 83.: 83.: 93.: 93.: 83.: 8.3.9.3: 98.: 98.: 98.: 98.: 88.: 88.: 83.: 83.: 83.: 8.2.8-: 8:... 89.. 89... 88.. 82.... 89.. 89.. 93.. 93.. 2:: 9.93.9... .8238. 3.9-: 99.: 5.88: 28: 9.: Co .. 2.2.8: 8.35.20 >882: :8 .oz .2: .oz .2: 82 :8 .oz .2: .02 .:.m :52... .:.m 8:8 .2: «so: :8 2:0: 8.6.56 2:: .:.m 2:8 .2: 2:8 :8 2:8 :8 2:8 .2: 2:8 .2: 2:8 .:.m .82 .:.m .8... .2: .8... 8.558 320 .989. .989. .839. .839. .989. .939. .839. .899. .889. 2.2.8.. :9:9 85.9 859 88.9 88.9 8.:9 35.9 95.9 85.9 8.3.3:... v :3 .89.... .89.... .839. .999. .889. ...:89. .989. .899. .859. 2.2.8.. 889 889 989 8.:9 859 9:9 839 ..89 98.9 8.33:3: : :3 .389. .889. .699. .999. .599. .88.:. .9 .:.9. .939. 8.9. 2.2.8.. 95.9 86.9 9 .:.9 98.9 58.9 58.: 88.9 389 889 5.238: N :3 .889. .389. :89. .989. .899. .389. .88 9. .989. .889. 2.2.29. «8:9 889 989 :39 85.9 8.:9 98.9 859 38.9 8.8.8:: . :3 .839. .899. .859. .889. :89. .889. .9 89. .839. .889. 2.2.89. 839 93.9 98.9 93.9 839 88.9 88.9 33.9 989 83:8: .556 2.88.9. ....889. ....881 588.1 ....891 ....88...-. ....8:...1 ....881 ....881 2.2.8-. 8 .:.9 98.9 989 :89 33.9 8 6. .. 33. .. ..9o. .- 88. .. .31... 8... .828. ...98. .. ..39. .. ...:9. .. ..89. .. ..33. .. ...9:..~. ...... .m.~. ....93.~. ....m3..:. 2.2.8.. 3.3.: .83 88.: 89.: 89.: 9 .m: 88.: 93.: 3 9.: 999 8:. 8:88. ..9 .o. .. ...33. .. ... ...8. .. ...83. .. ..88. .. ..88. .. .99... .88. .. .89... 2.2.8.. .93 89.: 99.: 98.: 39.: 83.: 89.: 89.: 89.: 8...: 2.26:. ...88. .. ...9.~.~. ....8..~. ...38. .. ..88. .. ...:9. .. .5... .. 999:. 393. 2.2.8.. .38: 09: ...88.~. ...88.~. ...89a. ...98a. ...89. .. ..88. .. .89. .. .88.:. 58:. 2.2.8-. .88: 23:1 ....88.:. 2.9.0:. ....«8:.:. ....83.~. ...:k...~. ...3. ..N. .38. .. .99... .88.:. 2.2.8.. 80 89.: 89.: 89.: 38.: .80: 99.: 9.9.: 89.: 3.9.: 8.83 8.22.8 : :3 9 :3 o :3 u :3 v :3 n :1. u :3 . :3 .556 28.: 8.88: 28: 9.: ....88.~. ....motd. ....:~8.~. ....98.:. 3.39.... ....9..~.:. ....98.:. ....93.n. ....8.m.:. 2.2.8.. 83.: :89: 38.: 88.: 98:: .8... 8.3 99.9 «8:9 .588 : o 9 m m .. n N . 2.2.2: .0 28:; 9.2.9....m 82.23:. on: :88. :3 28:9 28:88 .80 8.. 6.88: 28: 9.: .0 88m .828. 2.. a. 2.8:: 8.828: . ..m 28» 114 is determined by comparing the sum of squared residuals and adjusted coefficient of determination across alternative specifications. Looking at the non-nested regression criteria, the seventh lag of the stock of PHS funded basic research has the smallest sum of squared residuals and the largest adjusted r—squared. While this is the preferred timing and will be used in all subsequent discussion, it should be noted that the values of the non- nested regression criteria are not much different for the sixth and eighth lags of PHS basic research. 5.42 The Magnitude and Significance of PHS Basic Research Table 5.1 reveals that the stock of basic research begins to influence pharmaceutical investment as early as three years following research award. The constant elasticity estimate is smallest and insignificant in the concurrent year while, with each passing year, the magnitude and significance of the effect increases until the seventh lag. Given that research awards are used to measure the PHS public knowledge stock, it is sensible that its immediate impact would be small relative to longer lags. Longer lags allow for the process of doing scientific research and the process of communicating results. Referring to column (8) of Table 5.1, it is clear that the coefficient on the PHS funded stock of basic research is statistically significant. Without correcting for heteroscedasticity or serial correlation in the model, publicly funded research has a t-statistic of 3.32 (p-value < 0.001 ). Accounting for 115 heteroscedasticity reduces the t-statistic to 2.29 (p-value < 0.05) while the HISC robust t-statistic drops further to 2.14 (p—value < 0.05). The magnitude of the impact indicates that industry R&D investment responds strongly to the stock of PHS basic research. A 1% increase in this stock will result in a 0.46% increase in industry R&D after seven years. At the sample mean, the marginal effect on pharmaceutical investment is about $166 thousand per million of public basic research. Alternatively, a 1% increase in the stock of basic research in 1978 ($70.6 million) would have induced $13.7 million in pharmaceutical investment by 1985. Using this estimate with the marginal impact of industry R&D on approved NCEs calculated in chapter four, a $1 million increase in the PHS research stock produces a marginal physical product of 0.01 approved NCEs in each of the seven therapeutic classes. This amounts to a total increase in pharmaceutical innovation of 0.07 additional approved NCEs. Using the present discounted stream of revenue earned by the average NCE (estimated by Grabowski and Vernon (1996)), the additional 0.07 approved NCEs will produce a discounted present value of $10.3 million in additional revenue at the time of introduciton. The results suggest that industry firms are investing in response to research opportunities created through federal extramural funding of research. The emergence of our national research enterprise following World War II has created productive and profitable research opportunities for industry. Public basic research, which is conducted largely in academic institutions, creates a foundation of public knowledge that contributes to industry efforts to conceive 116 new therapeutic outcomes. This is not to say that the interaction between publicly funded research and industry research is unidirectional. Case study evidence has been used to shed light on the complexity of the relationship (Henderson and Cockbum (1997)); however, the purpose here is to generalize beyond a handful of specific case analyses and test whether there exists a broader relationship. Moreover, until now, we have not had any broader evidence on the timing, magnitude and significance of this relationship. 5.43 Public Regulation and Industry Demand Table 5.1 shows that the estimates of the impact of FDA review time are not statistically significance either individually of jointly. This finding differs from the findings of Wiggins as well as with some of the findings of Ward and Dranove. In his linear model, Wiggins found that each of the second through the fifth lags had a significantly negative impact on industry R&D (a comparison with Wiggins’ results appear in section 5.5). His interpretation describes regulation as reducing the number of new compounds entering the industry’s innovative process. Ward and Dranove (1995), using the log of expected approval times calculated from a first stage regression, find that review times are either insignificant or have a positive and significant effect on industry R&D investment. Their preferred interpretation characterizes their estimate as a measure of the cost of FDA compliance plus the increase in rents associated with intellectual property protection. The interesting contrast between the 117 findings here and those of Ward and Dranove is that their regulatory measure became positive and significant in their regression that included the distributed lag of NIH obligations. In Table 5.1, the signs of all regulatory variables are negative. Although no statistical significance is found, this may suggest that Wiggins’ interpretation is most relevant here. It is also the case, however, that excessive noise and collinearity in the average review time measures are leading to imprecise estimates. These results provide an interesting contrast to Wiggins (1983) results obtained using the period of 1971-1976. In his regressions the second through the fifth lags of regulatory stringency were significant. This implies that there has been some type of change in the behavior of pharmaceutical firms toward FDA regulation. It may be that interacting with the FDA early in the discovery stage and investing in “governmental affairs” departments have transformed FDA regulation into a fixed cost rather than a variable cost of innovation. Further investigation into the impact of FDA regulation seems warranted. Column (8) of Table 5.1 shows the elasticity of industry investment with respect to industry sales. With a point estimate of 0.24, a 1% increase in sales leads to a 0.24% increase in industry R&D investment. In 1985, for example, a 1% increase in sales implies a $7.1 million increase in industry R&D investment in that same year. Moreover, the sales variable is statistically significant with a t-statistic of 1.98 (p-value < 0.05). The regression results in Table 5.1 include US. disease incidence for the 45-64 age group and US. disease severity for the 15-44 age group. The other 118 age groupings were insignificant and were dropped from the equation. The elasticity estimates indicate that a 1% increase in disease incidence results in a 0.40% increase in pharmaceutical investment. For disease severity, on the other hand, a 1% increase in the number of hospital days results in a 0.90% decrease in pharmaceutical investment. The impact of disease incidence on investment is in the expected direction. The impact of severity, however, was not expected to lower pharmaceutical investment. It is unclear why longer hospital stays would lower investment in drug research. Yet, the effect is strongly significant was a t-statistic of -3.99 (p-value < 0.0001 ). 5.5 Wiggins (1983) Revisited Because of the similarity between this analysis and Wiggins (1983), it is interesting to re-examine the original Wiggins (1983) results it light of the new data available. In Table 5.2 his original model is estimated using the current data. For these regressions, the model is linear in the levels, all variables are in nominal dollars and the sample period is 1971-1976. Wiggins (1983) results appear in the right most column while the regressions with the current data are in columns (2) through (7). Although there may be slight differences in the measurement of PhRMA sales and R&D, the primary difference here is the introduction of a public basic research measure that was unavailable to Wiggins. Also, these regressions include an additional therapeutic class in the cross- sectional dimension, namely the gastrointestinal/genito-urinary class. Table 5.2 - Re-Enmindion of the Wiggins Model 119 Dependen Variable = Level of lndustg R&D lnvedment Equations Wiggins 2 3 4 5 6 7 Intercen nla 84.417 81.948 83.712 22.764 25.853 26.69 [5757]“ [5563]“ [5714]“ [0.931] [0.993] [1.200] PHS Basic Research 0.234 0.217 0.216 [2867]“ [2572]“ [3.170 " Sales 0.047 0.080“ 0.0645 0.0727 0.046 0.052 0.043 [2.47] [4861]“ [3019]“ [3219]“ [2.3141' [2.409}‘ [2.347]' Reguldion (curred) -0.067 -0.049 0056 -0.064 -0.068 -0.058 [-1 .041] [-O.744} [-0.840] {-1.084} {-1 .148} {-1 .028] Reguldion (leg 1) -0.070 -0.048 -0.052 -0.057 -0.058 -0.05 [-1.310] [0837] [-0.914] [-1.122] [-1.142] {-1 .059] Reguldion (1392) -0.486 -0.131 -0.102 -0.103 -0.114 -0.111 -0.105 {-2 .38] [2589]“ [-1 .817}' {-1 .807}' [-2.269]' {-2.170]‘ [-2.341]' Reguldion (leg 3) -0.773 -0.131 -0.109 -0.141 -0.129 -0.146 -0.121 [~3.65] [-2.422]“ [-1 .9241' [-2.161]‘ {-2.529]“ [2498]" {-2.580]“ Reguldion (leg 4) -0.885 -0.056 -0.05 -0.066 -0.076 -0.075 -0.072 [-3.44} {-0.938} {0825] {-0.927] {-1.395} [-1.170] {-1.364] Reguldion (leg 5) -0.481 0.008 0.007 -0.52 -0.005 -0.038 -0.004 {-1.80] [0.111] [0.101] {0585} [-0. .79] [-0.474} {-0.068] CNS dummy n/a -29.179 -20.333 -23.341 32.798 26.95 31.071 [-1.650] {-1.062] [-1.211] [1.303] [1.033] [1.271] Cardio dummy nla 15.769 10.022 16.428 48.484 48.802 43.93 [1.531] [0.881] [1.229] [2886]“ [2808]“ [3482]“ Anti-inf dummy n/a 15.934 17.853 18.052 61.6111 58.266 58.733 {1.905]‘ [2.106}' [2.125]‘ [3620]" [3.351)“ [3830]“ Gl/GU dummy -54.094 -57.85 -56.112 -8.841 -11.74 -13.672 [6325]“ [6358]“ [5960]“ [-0.467} {-0.611] {-0.926} Derm dummy nla -53.172 -61.01 -56.14 15.251 12.246 7.191 [5975]" {-5.477}" [4645]“ [0.537] {0.427} [0.350] Resp dummy n/a -26.431 -37.951 -26.077 44.383 44.237 34.849 {-1.708]‘ {-2.071]' [-1.166] [1.344] [1.305] [1.479] Time 2.426 -0.921 [1.158] [-0.419] YR 1972 5.946 2.163 [0.892] [0.351] YR 1973 3.485 -4.182 [0.462] [0566] YR 1974 12.457 0.92 [1.518] [0.107] YR 1975 14.891 1.932 [1.596] [0.198] YR 1976 5.423 -8.077 [0.482] l-0-7101 R-Squared 0.69 0.964 0.965 0.971 0.974 0.977 0.973 Rber-Squered nla 0.96 0.947 0.948 0.958 0.958 0.96 Num Obs 42 42 42 42 42 42 42 Note: All variables are in logs. Asymptotic t-stdistics are in brackets {1. Years: 1971-1976 “Significance I the 5% level. “Significance a the 1% level. 120 Columns (2) to (4) explore the relationship without incorporating research opportunities from publicly funded basic research. The estimates in column (2) show that concurrent sales and FDA regulation are significant and have the signs found by Wiggins. The impact of sales is twice that found by Wiggins and more statistically significant. Also, only the second and third lags of regulation are significant whereas the second through the fifth lags were significant in Wiggins’ regression. When a linear time trend and year dummies are introduced, Columns (3) and (4), the coefficients generally show lower significance and are slightly smaller. Although these differences are probably due to differences in the data sets, it is broadly confirmed that average review times did lower industry R&D expenditure in this period. Columns (5) through (7) introduce publicly supplied research opportunities into the relationship using the seventh lag of PHS funded research. The change in the estimates is quite interesting. First, the intercept and the therapeutic class dummies change dramatically. This is to be expected since these variables were postulated to capture the effects of research opportunities by Wiggins. Second, the estimate of industry sales falls and is now in line with the his original estimate. Third, the second and third lags of regulation are now more significant than previously although they are quite a bit smaller in magnitude than Wiggins’ original estimates. The most preferred specification appears in column (7). Here, the insignificant time variables are excluded. Public basic research has a strong 121 and large impact on the level of industry R&D investment. With an estimate of 0.22, each additional dollar of public basic research leads to a 22 cent increase in industry R&D investment seven years hence. This contrasts with the 4 cent increase resulting from an addition dollar of concurrent sales. Average review times have a significant impact in this sub-period although the fourth and fifth lags do not show any significance using the current data. Overall, Wiggins’ results are broadly confirmed. His exclusion of public research does not appear to have biased his sales and regulatory estimates. Revisiting his model has highlighted the importance of incorporating a measure of public research as well as shown that the effects of FDA review times on industry expenditure have changed over time. 5.6 Endogeneity Test for Scientific Opportunity It has been suggested that estimates of the relationship between public and private funding of research are biased by the endogenous response of funding agents to the same set of scientific opportunities. To explore this issue, a reduced form equation for the stock of PHS funded basic research is specified using disease incidence and severity instruments for public research. The reduced form equation is: (53) Bit = h('"Cit. SeVit) 122 where i represents the medical therapeutic class, t represents time. Bit is the stock of PHS funded basic research; lncit and Sevit are the measures of disease incidence and severity not already included in the estimation of equation (5.2). Ward and Dranove (1995) maintain that government funding is a function of disease prevalence and severity.3 While this is the basis for choosing the instruments for equation (5.3), there are two complications with Ward and Dranove’s view. The first involves their measures of publicly funded research while the second involves causation. Apart from timing issues related to their use of financial obligations versus awards, Ward and Dranove use a very broad measure of public health research that includes many special and large programs designed to address immediate health problems. One would reasonably expect that the funding of these programs has been driven more by measured prevalence and severity, however, one would also expect that these programs have been somewhat successful in lowering targeted disease prevalence and severity. Clearly, the causation problem comes from categorizing prevalence and severity as determining funding while they are also an outcome of this funding. Public research measured in this analysis is quite different from Ward and Dranove’s measure. Here, publicly funded basic research is analyzed. While it 3 Ward and Dranove (1995) measure disease incidence by the number of physicians in a particular specialty. While this measure is problematic for the obvious reason that physician specialties have only an indirect correspondence to disease prevalence. Here, disease incidence is used because systematic prevalence measures are not available. 123 is still conceivable that basic research funding responds to perceived incidence and severity, it is difficult to know exactly how scientific review groups choose projects to fund. Presumably, these decisions are based on some notion of scientific merit and not on short-term goals to lowering disease incidence and severity. In the long-run, funded basic research may well lead to lower incidence and severity indirectly through therapeutic compounds or other embodiments of this knowledge. Thus, the issues of how public projects are picked for funding and the direction of causation cloud the relations specified in equation (5.3). The most simplistic a priori expectations imply that funding of basic research responds positively to increases in incidence and severity, h1 > 0 and h; > 0. Using the heteroscedasticity robust version of the Hausman specification test, column (1) of Table 5.1 shows the calculated test statistic has a value of 2.351. Comparing this with the chi-squared (one degree of freedom) critical value reveals that the null hypothesis of exogeneity cannot be rejected at a 10% level or higher. Consequently, no evidence is found for endogeneity of publicly funded research and industry research. Table 5.3 shows the regression results of equation (5.3). As with industry sales, the regression includes the omitted measures of disease incidence and severity along with the other variables from equation (5.2). It is clear from this table that all the incidence and severity variables are insignificant. This contrasts with the maintained view of Ward and Dranove (1995). Their position holds that NIH funding of research responds positively to these variables in a Table 5.3 - PHS Basic Research Dependent Variable: PHS Basic Research (15% Dep.) Equation Variable or Statistic 1 Constant 1.8992 t-statistic [0.8674] Industry Sales -0.0670 t-statistic [-0.7004} Incidence (age 0-14yrs) 0.5866 t-statistic [0.3221] Incidence (age 15-44yrs) 0.1280 t-statistic [0.56447] Incidence (age 45-64yrs) 0.3543 t-statistic {1 .0703] Incidence (age 65+ yrs) 0.1202 t-statistic [0.3876] Severity (age 0-14yrs) 0.0047 t-statistic [0.0340] Severity (age 15-44yrs) 0.1081 t-statistic [0.5421] Severity (age 45-64yrs) —0.0124 t-statistic [-0.0425] Severity (age 65+ yrs) 0.1450 t-statistic [0.5025] Current Regulation -0.0413 t-statistic [-2. 1 778]" Lag 1 Regulation -0.0288 t-statistic {-1 6333]" Lag 2 Regulation -0.0255 t-statistic [-1 .3660] Lag 3 Regulation -0.0221 t-statistic [-1 .1 935] Lag 4 Regulation -0.0223 t-statistic [-1.1628] Lag 5 Regulation -0.0118 t-statistic [-0.6127} Class Dummies Sig. Time Dummies Sig. SSR 0.5370 R-Squared 0.9970 Number of Observations 105 Note: All variables are in logs. Asymptotic t-statistiqs are in brackets [1. Years: 1971-1985 'Significance at the 10% level. “Significance at the 5% level. 125 given year. The notion that funding responds to incidence and severity makes sense if one can properly account for the problems of timing and causation, which have not been adequately addressed in this specification. The timing problem comes from relating incidence and severity in a given year to funding in a given year. In our context that implies researchers are receiving awards for grant proposals prepared at roughly the same time as incidence and severity are being observed. Clearly, researchers must prepare proposals in advance and this relationship should not be expected to hold. The problem of causation was mentioned earlier. Consequently, the simple a priori expectations that h1>0 and h2>0 are not realized. Since the chosen instruments for public basic research are weak, this violates one of the properties that instruments must have in order to test for endogeneity. Consequently, the econometric test is uninformative. Nevertheless, scientific opportunity is unlikely to affect lagged public funding. The analysis finds that the relevant public and private funding decisions are separated by a seven year period. In order for scientific opportunity to be causing a simultaneity bias, the relevant scientific opportunities would need to remain constant over the seven year period. This seems unlikely. 5.7 Conclusion This chapter has explored the indirect impact of publicly funded research on pharmaceutical productivity. This effect works through industry R&D 126 investment to stimulate new product innovation. The analysis finds statistical support for an inducement effect of public basic research on industry R&D investment. Federally funded research begins to impact pharmaceutical investment as early as three years following financial award with its statistically strongest impact coming seven years after financial award. The effect is statistically significant with a heteroscedasticity/serial correlation robust t- statistic of 2.23 (p-value < 0.05). The magnitude of the impact is in the range of 0.42 to 0.46. The results imply a 10% increase in the stock of public basic research leads to a 4.2% to 4.6 % increase in industry R&D investment after seven years. When combined the marginal impact of pharmaceutical investment on approved NCEs, a marginal ($1 million) increase in the PHS research stock produces a marginal physical product of 0.01 approved NCEs in each of the seven therapeutic classes. This amounts to a total increase in pharmaceutical productivity of 0.07 additional approved NCEs. If this increase in innovative output earns the average discounted revenue, then a discounted present value of $10.3 million in additional revenue will be produced. The empirical results indicate that FDA review delays no longer affect industry R&D investment. This is not to say that FDA regulation imposes no costs on the industry. Review delays still have a direct impact on innovation (see chapter four) but do not seem to be increasing R&D expenditure for those compounds in the pipeline. The bulk of compliance costs appear to be borne early in the innovative process and are probably best measured using 127 proprietary data. Overall, Wiggins’ idea that FDA regulation keeps potential compounds from ever entering the innovative pipeline seems most accurate The elasticity of pharmaceutical R&D investment with respect to industry sales is 0.24. A increase of 1% in sales leads to a 0.24% increase in R&D expenditure. This would have increased industry investment by $7.1 million in 1985 and produced nearly $14.8 million in new revenues. It is also found that industry sales increase with disease incidence and fall with disease “severity.” A 1% increased incidence in the forty-five to sixty-four year old age group leads to an 0.40% increase in investment. The finding that disease “severity” in the fifteen to forty-four year old age group lowers industry investment is in the opposite direction of the expected effect. Finally, there was no evidence found that supports an endogeneity bias due to scientific opportunity between public basic research and private industry R&D investment. Although the econometric test is not informative, the fact that public research is lagged seven years makes a simultaneity bias due to scientific opportunity unlikely in our context. Chapter 6 The Total Impact of Public Basic Research on Pharmaceutical Innovation 6.1 Overview This chapter calculates the total impact of publicly funded basic research and FDA regulatory stringency on pharmaceutical innovation. Recall that the production framework identifies two related channels through which federally funded basic research can influence industry output. First, basic research can contribute directly to private industry’s product innovation. In this case, basic knowledge is used as a direct input to create the new product introduced by private industry. Second, this research can contribute indirectly to private industry’s product innovation. This indirect contribution recognizes the role that basic knowledge plays in stimulating additional private R&D investment. The channels of influence for FDA regulatory stringency are analogous to those of public research, however, having a negative impact instead of a positive impact. The total impacts are the sum of the direct effects (chapter four) and the indirect effects (chapter five). 128 6.2 The Total Impacts Recall from chapter three that the total impact is calculated as the sum of the direct and indirect marginal impacts. This relationship for PHS basic research is given by the following relation: (6.1) (int / dBit ) = ( int / dBit ) + ( int / dllt ) * ( dlit I dBit) where i is medical therapeutic class and t represents time; Yit is a count of approved new chemical entities; Bit is the stock of PHS funded basic research; 'it is the annual flow of industry R&D investment. The symbol, d, stands for the mathematical derivative. Estimates of the marginal impacts are obtained from the elasticity estimates. For example, the direct marginal impact of public research is calculated as follows: (6.2) (MP)B = (Elasticity)y3 * [ (Sample Average)yl (Sample Average)B ] (MP)B = (2.2) * [ (19) l (633.9879) ] (MP)B = 0.0659 Using the other estimated elasticities and sample period averages, the total impact of public basic research is: 129 130 (6.3) (Total MP)B = (0.0659) + (0.0458) " (0.1659) (Total MP)B = 0.0735 Further, using Grabowski and Vernon (1996), if the total marginal impact earns an average return, then the value of the total marginal product in each therapeutic class is: (6.4) (Value Total MP)B = (Total MP)B * (Avg. Discounted Value (1986$)) (Value Total MP)B = (0.0735) * ($193.1896) (Value Total MP)B = $14.20 Million 80, across all seven therapeutic classes: (6.5) (Value Total MP)a" masses = (7) * ($14.20) = $99.4 million It is evident that the total marginal impact of PHS basic research is determined mainly by the direct effect. The direct marginal impact (roughly 0.07) is seven times greater than the indirect marginal impact (roughly 0.01) on the number of approved NCEs. The indirect impact of PHS basic research must work through the marginal effect of private R&D before having an effect on the 131 number of approved new chemical entities. An increase in the marginal impact of private R&D will also increase the indirect effect of PHS basic research. Analogous to publicly funded basic research, the total marginal impact of FDA regulatory stringency is given by: (6.6) ( int I dRit ) = ( int I dRit ) + ( int I (“it ) * ( dlit I dRit ) where all terms are defined as before and Rit represents the annual regulatory delay (measured in months). Because none of the indirect elasticities were found to be statistically significant, the second term on the right-hand side of equation (6.6) is zero. This implies that the total marginal impact of FDA regulatory stringency is equal to the direct marginal impact. Because FDA regulatory stringency enters the empirical specification in chapter four as a nine period distributed lag, the total marginal impact of FDA regulatory stringency is calculated as the sum of the marginal impact of each Iag. Using estimated and sample values, this total marginal impact is: (6.6) (Total MP)R = Z (Elasticity)YR * [ (Sample Avg.)y I (Sample Avg.)R ] (Total MP)R = -0.284 132 Wiggins (1983) found the total impact of regulation came primarily from its direct effect. His estimate of the total effect is -0.156, which is quite a bit smaller than the direct effect found here. There are two reasons for the different findings. First, whereas Wiggins eliminated insignificant lags of stringency in his formulation, all lags were included in this analysis regardless of their statistical significance. There are no good a priori reasons to claim only certain lags matter. For instance, how sensible is it to say that lags two and five matter but that lags three and four are irrelevant? Second, a longer distributed lag was included in this analysis based on the interviews with industry regulatory personnel. Overall, the estimate of regulatory stringency is probably too large. 6.4 Recap of Dissertation Findings This dissertation has described the role of publicly funded basic research in the discovery and development of new therapeutic compounds. It is found that public basic research is a very important factor in pharmaceutical innovation and that knowledge extemalities from this research lead to industry-vvide increasing returns to scale. It was noted in the introduction that federal funding of basic scientific research is one of the traditional priorities of our national research policy. The objective has been to build a productive foundation of knowledge that will stimulate national and industry innovation and growth. This dissertation has provided some evidence that, at least in part, this objective has been achieved. 133 Overall, this analysis has found evidence that the basic research component of our national research policy has been successful in stimulating industrial innovation. The analysis suggests that the decline in the growth rate of federal basic research spending will have a negative impact on pharmaceutical innovation. Although this result is found within the context of biomedical research and the pharmaceutical industry, it could be that federal R&D is quite important to industrial innovation and economic growth. The main results from the estimation of the direct impact of PHS basic research and FDA regulatory stringency on the production of new chemical entities in the pharmaceutical industry are: 1. Publicly funded basic research has an economically and statistically significant direct effect on pharmaceutical innovation. The elasticity of the number of new chemical entities with respect to the stock of public basic research is found to lie in the range of 2.2 to 2.5. 2. Public basic research has a distinct role in the pharmaceutical innovative process. PHS basic research contributes to the creative conception of new avenues to therapeutic outcomes and helps guide the parameters used in chemical screening. Because public basic research affects the drug concept period of pharmaceutical innovation, its impact comes early in the pharmaceutical innovative process. The data indicate that an average of 134 seventeen years elapse between the stock of federal awards and the introduction of new therapeutic compounds. 3. While still substitutes, public basic research and private industry R&D have limited substitution possibilities in the pharmaceutical innovative process. The estimated elasticity of substitution of 0.29 indicates that the pharmaceutical innovative process is closer to a fixed proportions technology rather than a more flexible substitution technology like the Cobb-Douglas. This reflects the different nature of the public basic research and private R&D and lends support to the hypothesis that a division of labor has emerged in the biomedical research SGCtOf. 4. Using the Grabowski and Vernon (1996) estimate of the average return to an approved NCE, the public basic research has a net present value of $5582 in real 1986 dollars at the time of introduction. 5. Pharmaceutical innovation is characterized by increasing returns to scale at the industry level. This result is a direct consequence of the availability of publicly funded basic biomedical research. 6. Product quality regulation by the Food and Drug Administration continues to have a negative direct effect on new chemical entity innovation. This is a pure 135 production effect, however, and does not include any of the possible benefits stemming from increased safety and efficacy. The main results from the estimation of the indirect impact of public basic research and FDA regulatory stringency are: 1. Public basic research has an economically and statistically signification indirect effect on pharmaceutical innovation by acting to induce private industry R&D investment. The magnitude of this impact is in the range of 0.42 to 0.46. This implies a 1% increase in the stock of public basic research leads to a .43% to .46% increase in industry R&D investment after seven years. 2. The empirical results find no significant impact of regulatory delay times (in months) on pharmaceutical investment. This result contrasts with the findings of Wiggins (1983). It may be that, in the sample period, compliance costs are more accurately thought of as fixed costs rather than variable costs of innovation. 3. The elasticity of pharmaceutical R&D with respect to industry sales is estimated to be 0.24. A 1% increase in industry sales in 1985 ($202 million) would have increased industry investment by $7.1 million in that year. Using the estimated impact of industry R&D on the number of approved NCEs, this increase produces 0.01 additional therapeutic compounds in each therapeutic class after twelve years. 136 4. It is also found that industry investment increases with disease incidence and fall with disease “severity.” A 1% increased incidence in the forty-five to sixty- four year old age group leads to an 0.40% increase in investment. With regard to disease “severity,” the analysis indicates that pharmaceutical investment falls as the number of inpatient days increase. This underlying reason for this is unclear. 5. There was no evidence found that supports an endogeneity bias due to scientific opportunity between public basic research and private industry R&D. Unfortunately, because of the weakness of the instruments, the econometric test is uninformative. Nevertheless, any bias due to scientific opportunity is unlikely since the funding decisions are separated by a seven year period. 6.5 Future Research As one might image, there are numerous unanswered questions that deserve research. Here are a few that come to mind: 1. What characteristics help or hinder a firm’s ability to exploit the pool of public research? 2. How do these factors affect their competitive position in the industry and their productivity? 137 3.. How do NCEs affect health output measures and, in turn, affect GDP and national economic growth? Further, how can these insights improve our estimate of the social return to public basic research? 4. How does federally funded basic research, or any other type of federal sponsorship, affect other industries in our economy? APPENDICES APPENDIX A APPENDIX A Keywords Used to Construct PHS Basic Research Variables This appendix lists the keywords and character stings used in the data filters. Copies of worksheets were not able to be formatted for this appendix. 138 139 Table A.1 - Listing of Class Filter Keywords or Character Strings Note: After running each of these filters, the results must be inspected. Character strings typically capture more than is desired. Anti-lnfective Class: IAMEBICIDEI, ITRICHOMONICIDEI, [ANTHELMINTIC], /ANT|B|OTICI, [CYCLINES[, ICEPHAU, ICILLINI, ['THROMYCINI, /STREPTO[, IISONIAZIDI, [MALARIA], NIRAU, NIRUSI, IFUNGI, [BACTERIA], [PARASIT/ Endocrine/Neoplasm Class: [HORMONE], [CORTIC], [ANDRO/, [ESTRO], [PROGESTO], IDIABETI, ITHYROIDI, [INSULIN], IANABOLICI, IENDOCRINI, INEOPLASMI, [CANCER], [TUMOR], [CARCINI, [CHEMOI Cardiovascular Class: [HEART], ICARDIOI, ICOAGUI, DIGITALISI, [HEMOSTAT], [HYPOTENSIVE], NASO], IHEPARINI, IARRYTHMIC], [CALCIUM] Central Nervoufs Svstem Clas_s: IPARASYMPATHI, [MUSCLE], INARCOTICI, IOPII, [SALICY[, [ASPIRIN], ]ACETAMIN[, ICONVUU, [DEPRESS], [BRAIN], [NERV[, [TRANQUIL], IAMPHETAI, [ANOREX], [SEDAT], [ANESTHE[, [ARTHR|], [HYPNO], ] EYE ], [OPHTHA], [MYDRIA], [MIOTIC], ] EAR I, IAURII, [RHEUMA], [NEURO/ Gastro-intestinallGenito-Urinam Class: ] RENAU, [URINE], [KIDNEY], [NEPH/, [UREML lBlLE/, [GASTR], [INTESTINE[, [COLIN], [CHOLERETIC], [CHOLESTEROU, [EMETIC], lHISTAMlNE/, [CHOLINERGICL [LIPID], [GENITO], [CHOLAGOGUE], ['I'HIAZIDEI, [DIURETIC] Denhatologic Class: ISKINI, IDERM/, IQUTANI, ISEBACEI, IDANDRUFFI, ISEBOR/ Respiratom Class: ILUNGI, [PULMONARY], lBRONCHl, [RESPIR/ 140 Table A2 - Listing of Exclusion Filter Keywords or Character Strings Note: After running each of this filter, the results must be inspected. Character strings typically capture more than is desired. [OGRAPHI, [OGRAM[, [SURGICAU, [DETECTION], [INTOXICATION[, [ BCGI, [POPULATION], [EXERCISE], ['l'OXICOLOGYl, [PATIENT], [RHEUMAT|C[, [CONTRAST], [CLINICAL], [DIAGNOS[, [HUMAN], [INVESTIGAT[, [ DRUG], [RADI], [ MAN ], [INDICATOR], [ AGE [, [DEATH], [TEACH], [AGEING], [FITNESS], [THERAPY], [PEOPLE], [PERFORMANCE], [ADOLESCENT], [NATIONAU, [SUPPORT], [REHAB], [ENVIRON], [DENTAL], [EMOTION], [CENTER], [LITERATURE], [MORTALITY], [CONSUM[, [FOLLOW-UP], [PREGNAN/, [INFORMATION], [PROCEDURE], [COMMUNITY], ] AGENT], [TECHNIQUE], [ DIET], [SCREEN], [X-RAY], [COOPERAT[, [PREVAU, [LEARN], [URBAN], [AREA], [NURS[, [LIFE], [CHILD], [ EEG [, [ EKG ], [VCG l, [FETAL], [INFANT], [DATA], [OMETER[, [PANEU, NACCINEI, [NEONATAL], [RESEARCH], [INSTRUMENT], [EQUIPMENT], [ULTRASOUND], [PUBLIC], [FELLOWSHIP], [PROGRAM], [DIRECTORY], [TREATMENT], [NUTRITION], [THERAPEUTIC], [EVALUATION], [MEASUREMENT], / YEAR], [COLLABORAT[, [ TRAIN], [PREVENT], [INDUSTR], [COMMITTEE], [INSTITUTE], [CONGRESS] 141 Table A.3 - Activity Code Breakdown 1ST Round Elimination: Activity Code Breakdown Year: Activity Code Number of Grants Total Value of Grants Total Value - All Grants A?? - Applied Training 0?? - Construction Grants D?? - Environmental Demo E?? - Gen Support Education F04 - Nursing Fellowship F09 - Scientific Evaluation F10 - Fellowship Traineeship F11 - Direct Traineeship F13 - Hlth Science Scholars F15- Fogarty Scholarships F17 - Clinical Fellowship F35 - Visiting Scientist Fello G?? - National Lib of Med H?? - Staffing Grants J?? - Joint Facilities Grants K08 - Clinical Investigator K09 - Scientific Evaluation K10 - Special Proj. (NLM) M01 - Gen. Clinical Res. Ctr N43 - Sm. Bus. Innovation U?? - Cooperative Agreemnts 1 42 Table A3 (con’t) P02 - Categ. Clinical Res Ctr P06 - Animal Resources P07 - Biotech. Resources P09 - Scientific Evaluation P10 - Envir. Hlth Centers P11 - Pharma - Toxic Centers P13 - Dental Res Inst. Prog P15 - Outpatient Clin. Res. P16 - Hlth Services Res. Ctr. P17 - Spec. Centers of Res. P18 - Sickle Cell Centers P20 - Exploratory Grants P30 - Center Core Grants P40 - Animal Resources P41 - Biotech. Resource P50 - Specialized Center P60 - Comprehensive Ctr R02 - Nursing R04 - Anthropology R06 - Translation R07 - Int’l Ctr for Res. & Tr. R09 - Scientific Evaluation R10 - Coop. Clinical Res. R11 - MH Project Grants R12 - MH Special Grants R13 - Conferences R14 - Psycopharm Conferen R15 - MH Project Conferen R16 - MH Special Conferen R18 - Hosp. & Med. Facility R20 - MH Hosp. lmprovemt R21 - Comm. Hlth Explore R24 - Biotech. Resources R25 - Drug Abuse Education R26 - Oregan Project NCI R27 - Computer Technology R43 - Sm Bus. Innovation R44 - Sm Bus. Innovation 143 Table A3 (con’t) S?? - Gen. Research Support T?? - Training Grants W?? - Foreign Currency Prog Activity Code - Rnd 1 Total After Eliminating inappropriate Institutes File Name # of Grants Value of Grants After Direct Edit of Some Study Sections File Name # of Grants Value of Grants After Eliminating inappropriate and Individual review Study Sections File Name # of Grants Value of Grants After Exclusion Grants are eliminated File Name # of Grants Value of Grants After Eliminating Class Filtered Grants File Name # of Grants Value of Grants APPENDIX B Table 3.1 -Industry Lag 12. ms Log 15 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood @8616 Sum of Sqr Resid 12920239 R-Squared 0.77136 Sigma Squared 0.83227 Parameter one 5.98m curird 1.15545 lg1ird -2.31443 I92ird 1.66644 Igaird omeee lg4ird 1.10461 lgSird -1 792$ lgeird 0.27066 lngrd 1 £331 6 I98ird -1.(9250 ngird 0.682(9 IgIOird 07666) lg11ird -1.14263 Igl 2ird 1.77680 curreg -0.17164 lagreg1 -0.®19 Iagreg2 015877 lagrega 0.15317 lagreg4 0.20658 lagregs 00.1 lagregG 013434 lagreg7 0.16862 IagregB 031037 IagregQ 0.122% PHS15 1.2656 y79 0&1 7 y80 068464 y81 0.625% y82 -0.72731 y83 -1.44171 y84 -1.19476 yes 0.6175 y86 -1.72244 y87 -1 .65000 we -1 .44204 y89 -1 58:5 ya) -1.751$ y91 -1 .42518 y92 -1 56855 m -1.81371 y94 -2.24712 cns 1&82 cer 1.2288) ant 1.181(1) glu 1.-15 der 3.61557 res 3.13959 APPENDIX B Estimate Poisson Std Err 7% 0% 1.32721 1.29748 1.2%16 1.26134 1.29478 1.3131) 1.28813 1.2% 1.1381 1.1164) 1.11Cm 1.12% 0.18201 0.18278 0.17m2 0.191% 144 Regresion Tables 1 .3452 0.74371 -1 .19070 -1 .‘76 -1 .1 1- -1 some -1 4% 0.76431 -2.027CB -1 .8337 -1 64% -1 cm -1 .644!) -1 .41 159 -1 .47322 -1 .621m -1 .0“ Robust Std Err 3.25441 0.581 71 1 .1 2%4 0.74268 0.56412 0.45215 0.7700 1 .2253 Tabb 8.2 - Industry Lag 12. PHS Lag 16 Num of Obs 1 19 Log Likelihood 91.17339 Sum of Sqr Resid 128.15357 R-Squared 0.77272 Sigma Squared 0.82233 Parameter one -10.74545 curird 1.10170 Ig1ird -2.34392 Ig2ird 1.77701 Ig3ird 0.08301 lg4ird 1.07848 IgSird -1.79714 Ig6ird 0.29062 lg7ird 1.09895 IgBird -1.15806 Ig9ird 0.69966 lg1 Oird -0.77551 Ig11ird -1.1553O lg12ird 1.77984 curreg -0. 16304 lagreg1 -0.08536 lagreg2 0.06286 lagregB 0.16140 lagreg4 -0.19819 IagregS -0.06001 Iagreg6 013222 Iagreg7 0.16182 IagregS —0.31305 lagregQ -0. 12147 PHS16 1.57734 y79 -0.44796 y80 -O.88680 y81 -0.86420 y82 -1.00715 y83 -1.79105 y84 -1.621 13 y85 -1.09807 y86 -2.20950 y87 -2. 12652 y88 -1 .94485 y89 -1 .98685 y90 -2.25026 y91 -1.87157 y92 -2.10300 y93 -2.34943 y94 -2.77261 cns 1.67014 car 1 .39096 ant 1.37417 giu 1.89649 der 4.65524 res 3.95849 145 Estimate Poisson Std Err 7.35637 0.96847 1.32962 1.30730 1.29939 1.26202 1.29521 1.31893 1.28128 1.25546 1.12952 1.11262 1.10405 1.12311 0.18212 0.18284 0.17980 0.19239 0.18609 0.17476 0.15075 0.14378 0.13943 0.13694 1.00720 0.49728 0.62393 0.65756 0.73431 0.87077 0.95747 0.98151 1.02092 1.03901 1.04986 1.06272 1.11290 1.14285 1.23565 1.28616 1.36080 0.65256 0.73990 0.72820 1.08711 3.58166 2.56357 Poisson t-stat -1.46070 1.13756 -1.76285 1.35930 0.06389 0.85456 -1.38752 0.22035 0.85769 -0.92242 0.61943 -0.69701 -1.04642 1.58475 -0.89521 -0.46687 0.34963 0.83890 -1.06504 -0.34339 -0.87706 1.12546 -2.24516 -0.88702 1.56606 -0.90082 -1.42131 -1 .31425 -1.37156 -2.05686 -1.69314 -1.1 1876 -2. 16423 -2.04669 -1.85248 -1.86960 -2.02198 -1.63763 -1.70194 -1.82670 -2.03748 2.55935 1.87993 1.88707 1.74453 1.29974 1.54413 Robust Std Err 3.84133 0.59789 1.10986 0.75980 0.56013 0.43524 0.75457 1.21700 1 .07382 0.40658 0.22364 0.52962 0.93413 0.66734 0.12105 0.17461 0.04080 0.09765 0.15463 0.13123 0.1 1838 0.08381 0.04196 0.03960 0.43897 0.23666 0.49789 0.43536 0.39571 0.52323 0.41416 0.65359 0.55356 0.56337 0.65170 0.63232 0.51058 0.55630 0.69441 0.82054 0.76994 0.25996 0.31543 0.22826 0.52699 1 .80658 1.33418 Robust t-stat -2.79733 1.84265 -2.1 1 190 2.33878 0.14820 2.47791 -2.38166 0.23880 1.02340 -2.84827 3.12847 -1.46428 -1.23677 2.66707 -1.34687 -0.48888 1.54073 1.65282 -1.28172 -0.45730 -1.1 1686 1.93064 -7.46028 -3.06723 3.59331 -1.89283 -1.781 12 -1.98501 -2.54514 -3.42307 -3.91424 -1.68007 -3.99141 -3.77467 -2.98427 -3.14216 -4.40728 -3.36435 ~3.02848 -2.86326 -3.60106 6.42456 4.40971 6.02016 3.59869 2.57683 2.96697 Table 3.3 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 17 146 Num of Obs 1 19 Log Likelihood 91.95852 Sum of Sqr Resid 123.9466 R-Squared 0.78018 Sigma Squared 0.80209 Parameter Estimate Poisson Std Err one -14.94784 8.03942 curird 0.99723 0.97669 lg1ird -2.31566 1.33139 ngird 1.88129 1.31563 Ig3ird 0.09163 1.30071 Ig4ird 1.08264 1.26561 lgSird -1.83958 1.29377 lg6ird 0.32968 1 .32360 lg7ird 1 .05712 1.27798 lg8ird -1 . 18441 1.24679 ngird 0.72595 1.1 1794 Ig10ird -0.75210 1.10622 lg11ird -1.16089 1.09329 lgIZird 1.78054 1.11184 curreg -0. 13099 0.18373 lagreg1 -0.06742 0.18312 IagregZ 0.06974 0.17928 lagregB 0.16879 0.19272 lagreg4 -0.17713 0.18749 IagregS -0.04882 0.17568 Iagreg6 -0.11712 0.15160 lagreg7 0.15523 0.14378 IagregB -0.32239 0.14006 lagregQ -0.12015 0.13674 PHS17 2.24577 1.11445 y79 -0.66396 0.52246 y80 -1.29293 0.69995 y81 -1.42364 0.78793 y82 -1 .62679 0.87784 y83 -2.52620 1 .04281 y84 -2.50901 1.18256 y85 -2.08686 1 .24720 y86 -3.27177 1.31121 y87 -3.19974 1.32920 y88 -3.02900 1 .34432 y89 -3.11266 1.37219 y90 -3. 35031 1.40223 y91 -3.00123 1.43927 y92 -3.19322 1.50167 y93 -3.57331 1 .60249 y94 -3.99364 1.66661 cns 2.03827 0.70079 car 1.74313 0.76437 ant 1.80280 0.78715 giu 2.48982 1.18288 der 7.00553 3.96835 res 5.76062 2.89935 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err -1.85932 1.02103 -1.73927 1.42995 0.07045 0.85543 -1.42188 0.24907 0.82718 -0.94996 0.64936 -0.67988 -1.06183 1.60143 -0.71295 -0.36814 0.38900 0.87584 -0.94476 -0.27790 -0.77253 1.07967 -2.30181 —0.87868 2.01514 -1 .27084 -1.84716 -1.80682 -1.85317 -2.42249 -2.12168 -1.67324 -2.49523 -2.40726 -2.25319 -2.26839 -2.38927 -2.08524 -2.12644 -2.22985 -2.39627 2.90854 2.28047 2.29030 2.10489 1.76535 1.98687 5.05233 0.62046 1 .05362 0.78339 0.52276 0.42929 0.76288 1.19204 1.04266 0.40098 0.21318 0.53674 0.91383 0.67709 0.1 1670 0.17089 0.03666 0.09681 0.15500 0.13300 0.1 1778 0.08135 0.04350 0.03799 0.63143 0.26043 0.55439 0.55694 0.54240 0.65850 0.64261 0.89240 0.84657 0.81316 0.89355 0.89592 0.78376 0.851 12 0.97763 1.13946 1.11520 0.35530 0.40091 0.35561 0.67470 2.45558 1.82553 Robust t-stat -2.95860 1 .60724 -2.19782 2.40147 0.17529 2.52194 -2.41 137 0.27656 1 .01 387 -2.95376 3.40534 -1 .40124 -1 .27036 2.62970 -1 . 12246 -0.39451 1 .90229 1 .74363 -1 . 14275 -0.36707 -0.99437 1 .90833 -7.41 1 88 -3.16276 3.55667 -2.54946 -2.33217 -2.55617 -2.99926 -3.83631 -3.90442 -2.33848 -3.86474 -3.93495 -3.38985 -3.47424 4.27469 -3.52620 -3.26627 -3.13597 -3.5811 1 5.73674 4.34795 5.06957 3.69024 2.85290 3.15558 Table 3.4 - Industry Log 12, PHS Lag 18 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 91.86173 Sum of Sqr Resid 124.23301 R-Squared 0.77967 Sigma Squared 0.7988 Parameter one -16.85523 curird 1 .18978 Ig1ird -2.53168 lg2ird 1 .89409 IgSird 0.20049 lg4ird 1 .09517 lgSird -1 .76252 IgBird 0.13493 lg7ird 1 .19615 IgBird -1 .17591 ngird 0.77789 Ig10ird -0.74531 Ig1 1ird -1 .09928 lg12ird 1.65105 curreg -0.1 1481 lagreg1 -0.03943 lagregz 0.091 08 Iagreg3 0.16957 lagreg4 -0. 16014 Iagreg5 -0. 02758 lagre96 -0. 10975 lagreg7 0.16056 IagregB -0. 31 564 lagregQ -0.12226 PHS18 2.45921 y79 -0.75420 y80 -1 .49645 y81 -1 .74101 y82 -2.09261 y83 -3.00767 y84 -3.04816 y85 -2.76017 y86 -4.02915 y87 4.04022 y88 -3.88971 y89 -3.98873 y90 -4.27490 y91 -3.87720 y92 4.10684 y93 -4.40007 y94 4.92882 cns 2.1261 1 car 1 .77451 ant 1 .95389 giu 2.82042 der 7.94473 res 6.53707 147 Estimate Poisson Std Err 9.04179 0.96202 1.33779 1.31407 1.30197 1.26242 1.28799 1.31816 1.28012 1.24536 1.11559 1.09532 1.08902 1.09733 0.18465 0.18529 0.18032 0.19256 0.18793 0.17646 0.15243 0.14422 0.14015 0.13703 1.25845 0.55051 0.78531 0.94415 1.10748 1.28055 1.45812 1.59449 1.69614 1.75212 1.77806 1.81351 1.85980 1.87243 1.94921 2.00878 2.11542 0.75704 0.79651 0.88193 1.32733 4.51613 3.35521 -1.86415 1.23676 -1 .89244 1.44139 0.15399 0.86752 -1.36842 0.10236 0.93440 -0.94423 0.69729 -0.68045 -1.00942 1.50461 -0.62179 -0.21280 0.50510 0.88060 —0.8521 0 -0.15631 -0.72004 1.1 1329 -2.25222 -0.89218 1.95415 -1 .36998 -1.90555 -1.84400 -1.88953 -2.34873 -2.09047 -1.73107 -2.37548 -2.30591 -2.18761 -2.19945 -2.29858, -2.07068 -2.10693 -2.19042 -2.32994 2.80846 2.22784 2.21547 2.12489 1 .75919 1 .94834 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err 7.00221 0.54366 1.0031 1 0.80259 0.47088 0.44884 0.74645 1.13471 1.00713 0.39642 0.25455 0.55102 0.92808 0.64404 0.11402 0.17627 0.03927 0.09498 0.15268 0.13543 0.11962 0.08696 0.04473 0.03085 0.86351 0.31133 0.66652 0.68365 0.81186 0.88875 0.99182 1.25378 1.24355 1.25579 1.31417 1.37869 1.28076 1.33789 1.50169 1.59649 1.60156 0.42078 0.47012 0.53657 0.93097 3.34622 2.44434 Robust t-stat -2.40713 2.18848 -2.52383 2.35996 0.42578 2.43999 -2.361 19 0.1 1891 1 . 18768 -2.96633 3.05592 -1 .35260 -1 . 18447 2.56358 -1 .00699 -0.22369 2.31938 1 .78523 -1 .04883 -0.20365 -0.91751 1 .84633 -7. 05667 -3.96297 2.84790 -2.42251 -2.24516 -2.54665 -2. 57754 -3.38416 -3.07330 -2.20148 -3.24004 —3.21727 -2.95982 -2.89314 -3.33778 -2.89799 -2.73481 -2.75609 -3.07751 5.05284 3.77457 3.64143 3.02956 2. 37424 2.67437 Tabb 8.5 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 19 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 91.53659 Sum of Sqr Resd 127.28431 R-Squared 0.77426 Sigma Squared 0.80302 Parameter one -17.01 104 curird 1 .36312 |g1ird -2.50595 Ig2ird 1 .63343 lgBird 0.33780 lg4ird 1.13510 IgSird -1.64920 Ig6ird -0. 01 038 Ig7ird 1 .21742 Ig8ird -1.06137 IgQird 0.74666 Ig10ird -0.67758 lg11ird -1.08803 Ig12ird 1 .59672 cu rreg -0. 12167 lagreg1 -0.03537 IagregZ 0.1 1999 lagre93 0.17161 lagreg4 -0. 1 5797 lagregS -0.01 744 IagregG -0.09120 lagreg7 0.16485 lagregB -0.29141 IagregQ -0. 10866 PHS19 2.32217 y79 -0.74175 y80 -1 .48300 y81 -1 .78965 y82 -2.22354 y83 -3.22140 y84 -3.20792 y85 -2.97106 y86 -4.32853 y87 4.42292 y88 434573 y89 -4.46267 y90 -4.75709 y91 439654 y92 -4.57769 y93 -4.90143 y94 -5.32041 cns 2.00642 car 1 .59971 ant 1 .88666 giu 2.93351 der 7.79649 res 6.46526 148 Estimate Poisson Std Err 9.90278 0.95082 1.33868 1.29347 1.30286 1.26394 1.28275 1.32103 1.28293 1.24554 1.11634 1.09615 1.08610 1.09397 0.18412 0.18626 0.18394 0.19331 0.18742 0.17675 0.15527 0.14465 0.14063 0.13684 1.32597 0.56714 0.83386 1.05446 1.28440 1.51646 1.68699 1.87307 2.03202 2.13794 2.20778 2.25517 2.30701 2.33759 2.39065 2.46881 2.51723 0.76816 0.78214 0.93698 1.47742 4.91207 3.68214 -1.71780 1.43363 -1.87196 1.26283 0.25928 0.89807 -1.28568 -0.00786 0.94894 -0.85214 0.66885 -0.61815 -1.00178 1.45957 -0.66080 -0.18990 0.65235 0.88777 -0.84289 -0.09869 -0.58734 1.13961 -2.07224 -0.79406 1.75130 -1.30788 -1.77847 -1.69721 -1.73119 -2. 12429 -1.90157 -1.58620 -2.13017 -2.06878 -1.96837 -1.97886 -2.06202 -1.88080 -1.91483 -1.98534 -2.11359 2.61197 2.04530 2.01356 1.98556 1.58721 1.75584 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err 8.99025 0.46346 0.99654 0.74303 0.41995 0.42791 0.67260 1.10127 0.99495 0.37775 0.24815 0.49535 0.88948 0.60602 0.11728 0.18127 0.05348 0.09255 0.15646 0.13891 0.12564 0.09248 0.05139 0.03413 1.09466 0.37673 0.79073 0.85757 1.10249 1.27914 1.39818 1.70891 1.71372 1.84680 1.94086 2.02662 1.95646 2.00283 2.15861 2.26342 2.21860 0.51980 0.55163 0.71113 1.26145 4.34977 3.18631 Robust t-stat -1.89217 2.94120 -2.51466 2.19634 0.80438 2.65268 -2.45199 -0.00943 1.22360 -2.80974 3.00884 -1.36788 -1.22322 2.63476 -1.03741 -0.19512 2.24376 1.85428 -1.00966 -0.12557 -0.72584 1.78265 -5.67071 -3.18384 2.12137 -1.96891 -1.87547 -2.08687 -2.01684 -2.51841 -2.29436 -1.73857 -2.52581 -2.39491 -2.23908 -2.20203 -2.43147 -2.19516 -2.12066 -2.16550 -2.39810 3.85997 2.89997 2.65304 2.32549 1.79239 2.02907 Table B.6 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 20 Num of Obs 1 19 Log Likelihood 90.83429 Sum of Sqr Resid 131.57881 R-Squared 0.76664 Sigma Squared 0.81429 Parameter one -1 3.25281 cu rird 1 .53099 I91 ird -2.52755 ngird 1.54559 lgBird 0.29911 lg4ird 1 .19621 lg5ird -1.59851 lg6ird -0.07934 lg7ird 1 .27504 lgBird -0. 99498 ngird 0.75558 Ig10ird -0.71985 Ig11ird -1 .04268 lg12ird 1 .55646 curreg -0. 16055 lagreg1 -0.06735 lagregZ 0.10799 lagreg3 0.16713 lagreg4 -0.17005 IagregS -0. 02772 lagreg6 -0.11083 lagreg7 0.17732 lagregB -0.28141 IagregQ -0.09461 PHS 20 1.63038 y79 -0.53695 y80 -1.1 1344 y81 -1.31782 y82 -1.71974 y83 -2.65581 y84 -2.59026 y85 . -2.26236 y86 -3.58942 y87 -3.69891 y88 -3.63858 y89 -3.79473 y90 4.09076 y91 -3.72420 y92 -3.92292 y93 4.18404 y94 4.62526 cns 1.62135 car 1.17360 ant 1.441 13 giu 2.49809 der 5.64062 res 4.86635 149 Estimate Poisson Std Err 10.03849 0.94410 1.33895 1.28736 1.30127 1.26402 1.28582 1.32678 1.28927 1.24845 1.12858 1.10261 1.09804 1.09478 0.18127 0.18440 0.18604 0.19368 0.18666 0.17585 0.15455 0.14534 0.14138 0.13770 1.26380 0.54990 0.80466 1.04192 1.32695 1.58786 1.78136 1.96933 2.15845 2.31025 2.41646 2.50667 2.57070 2.60451 2.67893 2.72711 2.79686 0.72937 0.71539 0.91119 1.55845 4.95643 3.72179 Poisson t-stat -1.32020 1.62163 -1.88770 1.20059 0.22986 0.94635 -1.24318 -0.05980 0.98896 -0.79698 0.66950 -0.65286 -0.94958 1.42171 -0.88570 -0.36526 0.58046 0.86293 -0.91099 -0.15762 -0.71711 1.22002 -1.99044 -0.68708 1.29006 -0.97644 -1.38375 -1.26480 -1.29601 -1.67257 -1.45409 -1.14879 -1.66296 -1.60109 -1.50575 -1.51385 -1.59130 -1.42991 -1.46436 -1.53424 -1.65373 2.22294 1.64050 1.58159 1.60293 1.13804 1.30753 Robust Std Err 9.60317 0.42105 1 .03896 0.74496 0.43503 0.46578 0.66673 1 .12551 0.96059 0.37470 0.26688 0.48519 0.94429 0.59145 0.12646 0.18161 0.05746 0.08989 0.15254 0.13796 0.12405 0.09526 0.05250 0.04260 1.15563 0.38395 0.82843 0.90749 1 .27345 1 .48028 1.65556 1.95984 1 .99851 2.21879 2.32786 2.48762 2.42938 2.45295 2.61353 2.65734 2.64491 0.56739 0.56131 0.76637 1.45539 4.78334 3.53034 Robust t-stat -1.38004 3.63610 -2.43277 2.07473 0.68756 2.56819 -2.39753 -0.07049 1.32735 -2.65540 2.83117 -1.48366 -1.10420 2.63162 -1.26953 -0.37086 1.87931 1.85918 -1.11477 -0.20092 -0.89345 1.86150 -5.36050 -2.22075 1.41081 -1.39848 -1 .34403 -1.45216 -1.35045 -1.79413 -1.56458 -1.15436 -1.79605 -1.66709 -1.56306 -1.52545 -1.68387 -1.51825 -1.50100 -1.57452 -1.74874 2.85759 2.09083 1.88047 1.71644 1.17922 1.37843 Table 8.7 40110867ng 14, PHS Lag 15 Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R-Squared Sigma Squa'ed Parameter one curird Ig1 ird IgZird lg3ird Ig4ird IgSird IgSird lg7ird l98ird IgQird lg1 Oird lg1 1 ird lg1 2ird lg1 3ird lg1 4ird CUM harem |a9r092 lagreg3 lagreg4 lagr095 lagre96 lagreg7 IagregS lagreg9 PHS 15 y79 y80 y81 giu res 119 90.90157 1 29.37992 0.77054 0.85197 Estimate 0.14760 1.18817 -2.28047 1 .63929 0.02083 1.14889 -1 .78536 0.27812 1 .04768 -1.03038 0.74237 0.76909 -1 .17704 1 .92368 0.23783 0.04975 0.17698 0.09382 0.05876 0.15790 0.20435 0.05617 0.13363 0.16615 0.32172 0.12534 1.17209 0.34948 0.6563) 0.5852 0.68141 -1 .39859 -1 .13686 0.53664 -1 .66302 -1 .57337 -1 .34334 -1 .43101 -1 .68380 -1 .35843 -1 .49529 -1 .73125 -2.17736 1 .45506 1.13054 1.13643 1 .54721 3.20605 2.82824 150 PoissonStdErr 7.74675 0.97789 1 .35333 1.31338 1.32602 1.29618 1.32314 1.31809 1 .28783 1 .27786 1.17137 1.11853 1.12055 1.27742 1.17846 0.92015 0.18561 0.18410 0.17955 0.19264 0.18646 0.17598 0.15245 0.14398 0.14489 0.13968 1 .01325 0.48777 0.58310 0.61270 0.67683 0.78062 0.83772 0.86089 0.88566 0.91755 0.94408 0.96065 0.98424 1 .03888 1.09698 1.15693 1 .23115 0.64CBS 0.82768 0.71928 1.1209 3.72663 2.65649 Poisson t-stat -1.05174 1.21504 -1 .68508 1.24814 0.01571 0.88637 -1.34934 0.211% 0.81352 08(333 0.63377 0.68759 -1 .05042 1.50591 0.20182 0.05407 0.95346 0.50965 0.32727 0.81%3 -1.09599 0.31917 0.87660 1.15394 -2.2053 0.89735 1.15677 0.71648 -1.12657 0.95514 -1 11575 -1.79164 -1.35709 0.62335 -1.87771 -1 .71475 -1.4290 -1 .48962 -1.71076 -1.30759 -1.36309 -1 .49643 -1 .76855 2.2729 1.36590 1.57997 1.37887 0.86031 1 .W65 RobustStd Err 2.87593 0.70003 1 .29656 0.75374 0.63257 0.53177 0.55585 1 .18991 1 .1052 0.40464 0.33471 0.49002 0.97076 0.69324 1 .2204 1 .02329 0.08888 0.15855 0.04236 013801 0.14782 0.13546 0.143% 0.07684 003142 0.05331 0.29357 0.24348 0.44814 0.35249 0.27533 0.45676 0.27926 0.503% 0.33010 0.47532 0.56413 0.46764 0.39292 0.41547 0.52023 0.65664 0.56398 0.19888 0.2794 0.1626 0.42390 1 .26424 0.91642 Robust t-stat -2.83303 1 .67814 -1 .75885 2.17487 0.03294 2.16050 0.21197 0.23373 0.94794 -2.54641 2.21799 -1 .56951 -1 .21249 2.77493 0.19462 0.04862 -1 .99128 0.591 77 1 .38728 1 .61097 -1 .38249 0.41463 0.92866 2.16241 -1 0.2402 -2.35105 3.99259 -1 .43538 -1 .46583 -1 .66025 -2.47483 0.06201 4.07097 -1 .06497 5.03790 0.31010 -2.38124 0.06005 4.28531 0.26961 -2.87429 -2.63655 0.86073 7.31635 4.95987 7.00379 3.64993 2.53596 3.08620 Table an -Industry Lag 14,9113 Lag 16 151 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 91.19025 Sum of Sqr Resid 128.85904 R-Squared 0.77147 Sigma Squared 0.8436 Parameter Estimate Poisson Std Err one 40.43257 8.23952 curird 1.13276 0.98286 |g1ird 235071 1 .36CB2 1921rd 1.74460 1.32201 lg3ird 0.06326 1.33129 Ig4ird 1.13036 1.29805 lgSird -1 .82372 1 .32520 IgBird 0.29703 1 .31986 lg7ird 1 .09435 1 .28297 Igaird -1.11911 1.27902 ngird 0.70831 1.16940 ig10ird 0.78001 1.11597 1911ird -1.17824 1.11249 1912ird 1.88801 1.27307 lg13ird 0.21392 1.17451 Ig14ird 0.07237 0.93561 curreg 0.16918 0.18576 lagreg1 0.08309 0.18446 IagregZ 0.06281 0.17966 lagreg3 0.16432 0.19328 lagreg4 0.19821 0.18661 lagregS 0.05570 0.17640 lagreg6 0.13423 0.15229 lagreg7 0.15991 0.14408 lagrege 0.31800 0.14482 lagregQ 0.12003 0.13949 PHS 16 1.54099 1.10687 y79 0.44100 0.50046 y80 0.86963 0.64103 y81 0.84877 0.69863 y82 0.99019 0.78320 y83 -1.77162 0.91164 y84 -1 .58874 1.01015 y85 -1 .05943 1.07603 y86 -2.18728 1.09712 y87 -2.08350 1.11443 y88 -1.89390 1.16128 y89 -1.95991 1.16398 y90 -2.21981 1.18642 y91 -1.84057 1.20461 y92 0.08559 1 .30579 y93 -2.30827 1.36432 y94 -2.74053 1 .42389 cns 1.65465 0.68434 oar 1.36014 0.86449 ant 1.35713 0.76233 giu 1.85727 1.18900 der 4.50596 4.05068 res 3.84418 2.94711 Poisson t-etat -1.2%16 1.15252 -1.72806 1.319% 0.04752 0.87081 -1.37618 0.2504 0.85298 0.87497 0.60570 0.6%95 -1 .05910 1.48304 0.18214 0.07735 0.91076 0.45044 0.34960 0.85019 -1.06215 0.31580 0.88144 1.109% 0.19593 0.86055 1.3920 0.88120 -1.35%3 -1.21492 -1 .26429 —1 .94332 -1 .57 278 0.98457 -1.993% -1.86956 -1.63086 -1 .68380 -1.87101 -1 .52794 -1 .58187 -1.69189 -1 .92467 2.41788 1.57335 1.78024 1.56205 1.11240 1.30439 Robust Std Err 3.15896 0.71092 1 .28099 0.76883 0.62928 0.52466 0.56067 1 .17478 1 .08230 0.38493 0.36%8 0.49686 0.954% 0.69697 1 .19129 1 .(XJ941 0.08815 0.15754 0.04109 0.1%42 0.14997 0.13935 0.14091 0.07623 0.03318 0.05319 0.34473 0.24%1 0.47987 0.40708 0.33372 0.4%98 0.37210 0.59812 0.44791 0.53625 0.62%4 0.56827 0.44091 0.48%7 0.61979 0.76181 0.65833 0.21945 0.23651 0.1%95 0.44070 1 .44%9 1 .04398 Robust t-etat 0.30254 1 .59337 -1 .83508 2.2691 8 0.10053 2.15448 0.25276 0.25284 1 .01 1 14 -2.90729 1 .96707 -1 56%8 -1 .23419 2.70888 0.17957 0.07169 -1 .91935 0.52741 1 .52851 1 .63639 -1 .32165 0.39975 0.95262 2.09780 0.58485 0.25680 4.47013 -1 .78826 -1 .8124 0.08503 0.96709 0.79374 4.26970 -1 .77127 4.88325 0.88529 0.01078 0.44890 0.03467 0.82914 0.33273 0.03000 4.16288 7.54013 5.75087 7.10721 4.21436 3.12721 3.6824 152 Table ao-IMustryL-g 14,9113 Lag 17 Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R-Squared Sigma Squared Parameter one curird 191 ird 192ird lg3ird Ig4ird lgSird igSird lgTird ig8ird ig9ird lg1 Oird 191 1 ird lg1 2ird lg1 3ird lg1 4ird curreg lagreg1 lagre92 lagreg3 harem IagregS 119 91.9928 125.01129 0.77829 0.82484 Estimate -15.63597 1.02072 0.38800 1.85418 0.15004 1.14100 -1.91591 0.33602 1 .07129 -1 .18778 0%209 0.76293 -1 .16380 1.82159 0.16762 0.24676 0.13642 0.06019 0.06991 0.16989 0.17908 0.04777 0.1243 0.15334 0.31928 0.11332 2.33693 0.67546 -1.32054 -1 .48316 -1 .69586 0.594% 0.57953 0.18529 0.38240 0.28448 0.12928 0.23862 0.45537 0.09786 0.28999 0.67990 4.10218 2.08198 1.82986 1.85%1 2.58407 7.37585 6.04764 PoissonStdErr 9.04459 0.99206 1.36630 1.32980 1.33608 1.33233 1.32488 1.32624 1.28178 1.27232 1.16124 1.11092 1.09937 1.26272 1.16713 0.94359 0.18732 0.18492 0.17930 0.19407 0.18797 0.17688 0.15288 0.14420 0.14478 0.13910 1.23232 0.52829 0.72645 0.85184 0.95240 1.1%30 1.26585 1.38281 1.43332 1.44720 1.49931 1.52346 1.52174 1.54484 1.61144 1.72931 1.77749 0.74291 0.9022 0.82971 1.30831 4.51505 3.34453 Poisson t-stat -1 .72877 1 .02888 -1 .74779 1 .39433 0.1 1230 0.87612 -1 .44610 0.25337 0.83578 0.93355 0.57016 0.68676 -1 .05861 1 .44259 0.14362 0.26152 0.72826 0.32552 0.38992 0.87541 0.95273 , 0.27005 0.80080 1 .06342 0.20532 0.81488 1 .89637 -1 .27858 -1 .81779 -1 .741 13 -1 .78061 0.33901 0.03779 -1 .58032 0.35984 0.26954 0.08714 0.12583 0.270% 00530 0.04165 0.12796 0.30785 2.80249 2.02817 2.2969 1 .97512 1 .63362 1 8%2 Robust Std Err 3.72652 0.71%2 1 .23067 0.79024 0.60590 0.51480 0.58545 1 .14063 1 .04135 0.38%6 0.37129 0.48527 0.91760 0.69658 1 .14625 0.98671 0.08475 0.15262 0.03729 0.10490 0.15250 0.14179 0.14052 0.07095 0.03589 0.05061 0.46741 0.25539 0.51613 0.50219 0.42588 0.52502 0.52899 0.75508 0.66963 0.67713 0.75394 0.71737 0.58778 0.6%82 0.80177 0.97402 0.9026 0.29442 0.27772 0.26815 0.49973 1 .79%0 1 .3206 Robust t-stat 4.19586 1 .42156 -1 .94041 2.34634 0.24763 2.21638 0.27255 0.29459 1 .02875 0.04827 1 .78319 -1 .57219 -1 .26832 2.61503 0.14623 0.25009 -1 .60959 0.39441 1 .87478 1 .61945 -1 .17431 0.33688 0.87128 2.16121 0.89640 0.23908 4.99976 0.64486 0.55854 0.95339 0.98203 4.94205 4.87635 0.89409 0051 13 4.85062 4.15058 4.51455 0.87868 4.64574 4.10338 0.77807 4.54656 7.07137 6.58888 6.89923 5.17098 4.10544 4.57442 153 Table e10 - industry Lag 14,9113 Leg 13 Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R-Squared Sigma Squared Parameter one curird lg1 ird ngird lg3ird lg4ird lg5ird lg6ird lgTIrd lg8ird ngird lg1 Oird Ig1 1ird lg1 2ird lg1 3ird lg1 4ird curreg lagreg1 |a9re92 harem lagr995 Iagre96 lagreg7 PHS 18 119 91 .%163 125.45525 0.7775 0.81965 Estimate -17.03649 1.23589 0.58444 1.844% 0.21838 1.179% -1 .83132 0.14208 1.19965 -1.14207 0.75421 0.76149 -1 .12113 1 .77773 0.311370 0.21574 0.12369 0.03246 0%186 0.17391 0.16133 0.0269 0.11442 0.15753 0.31823 0.11683 2.49%3 0.75%4 -1 .50139 -1 .76582 0.12567 0.03923 0.0%24 0.79147 4.08416 4.%116 0.91344 4.04926 4.32187 0.91777 4.14306 4.43628 4.97599 2.14339 1.%3% 1.97437 2.84743 8%059 6.62497 PoissonStdErr 9.93585 0.97579 1.38251 1.32953 1.34025 1.29877 1.31492 1.32113 1.28491 1.26731 1.15299 1.10151 1.%716 1.25417 1.15088 0.93619 0.18813 0.18753 0.1%26 0.194% 0.18844 0.17739 0.15338 0.14459 0.14501 0.13927 1.35528 0.5562 0.81117 1.%459 1.18402 1.34932 1.53911 1.725% 1.82153 1.87347 1.93250 1.96856 1.98943 1% 2.%821 2.13771 2.23525 0.79042 0.91018 0.91817 1.44502 4.98715 3.7428 Poisson t-stat -1 .71465 1 .2%55 -1 88339 1 .38740 0.16294 0%840 -1 .39273 0.10754 0.93365 0.901 18 0.65414 0.%132 -1 .02185 1 .41746 0.26389 0.23045 0.65748 0.17310 0.5%62 0.%599 0.85612 0.127% 0.74598 1 .08949 0.19463 0.83888 1 .83728 -1 .3%32 -1 .85088 -1 .75775 -1 .79530 0.25241 -1 .99351 -1 .61824 0.24216 0.16772 0.02507 0.05%6 0.17241 -1 .97188 0.%321 0.07524 0.2615 2.71170 1 .98103 2.15%3 1 .97052 1.61627 1 .77030 RobustStd Err 5.87205 0.65%7 1.20752 0.81178 0.5552 0.51%5 0.56520 1.0%44 1.%4% 0.37404 0.38442 0.49393 0.98403 0.69550 1.07347 1.%572 0.08484 0.15655 0.%9% 0.10161 0.15113 0.14231 0.13875 0.07737 0.0402 0.04850 0.684% 0.29%2 0.%707 0.5%35 0%085 0.68794 0.85362 1.04401 1.01510 1.04381 1.05373 1.16527 1.01971 1.%3% 1.27388 1.34%2 1.3023 0.313% 0.31836 0.44945 0.75507 2.%321 1.86931 Robust t-stat 0.%128 1.88119 0.14028 2.2728 0.39332 2.29688 0.24014 0.13030 1.1%92 0.05334 1.96195 -1 .54171 -1.2%31 2.55%4 0.28292 0.21451 -1 .45799 0.20736 2.31505 1.71151 -1 .06749 0.15942 0.82462 2.03618 -7.91183 0.40%6 3.63567 0.55%1 0.47315 0.10146 0.1210 4.417% 0.59440 0.67379 4.02339 0.89071 0.713% 0.47495 4.23835 0.58344 0.25233 0.29%5 0.82113 6.83052 5.%363 4.39283 3.77106 3.02%4 3.54408 Table 3.11 - Industry Leg 14,9113 Lag 19 154 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 91 .62458 Sum of Sqr Resid 127.25382 R-Squared 0.77431 Sigma Squared 0.82386 Parameter Estimate Poisson Std Err one 46.11767 10.34160 curird 1 .39385 0.96560 lg1ird 0.46500 1 .37263 ngird 1.59014 1.31422 Ig3ird 0.24547 1 .34035 lg4ird 1 .21546 1 .29829 IgSird 4 .67098 1 .30557 lgGird 0.01540 1.32229 Ig7ird 1 .18550 1 .28314 198ird 0.98330 1 .25869 ngird 0.82051 1.15129 lg10ird 0.69222 1 .10140 lg11ird 4.14519 1.09726 lg12ird 1 .84273 1 .25399 lg13ird 0.39390 1 .14535 lg14ird 0.00249 0.90628 curreg 0.13162 0.18750 lagreg1 0.03491 0.18789 lagregZ 0.11930 0.18375 lagreg3 0.18001 0.19463 lagreg4 0.15725 0.18816 lagreg5 0.00979 0.17789 lagregG 0.09220 0.15624 lagreg7 0.16114 0.14486 lagrega 0.30668 0.14609 lagregQ 0.1 1058 0.13948 PHS 19 2.24172 1.35796 y79 0.73020 0.56909 y80 -1 .44586 0.84286 y81 -1 .73393 1 .07755 y82 0.15597 1 .31522 y83 0.15413 1.54379 y84 0.11338 1.71676 y85 0.83712 1 .92782 y86 4.22023 2.08425 y87 4.27725 2.18816 y88 4.16941 2.27918 y89 4.32351 2.32740 y90 4.62446 2.36300 y91 4.26988 2.38664 y92 4.44010 2.44092 y93 4.75124 2.52443 y94 -5. 19256 2.56489 cns 1 .98243 0.77503 car 1 .51830 0.83617 ant 1.86018 0.94627 giu 2.80734 1 .53762 der 7.3861 1 5.1 1447 res 6.13349 3.85676 Poisson t-stat 4.55853 1.44350 4.79582 1.2%95 0.18314 0.93620 4.27988 0.01165 0.92391 0.78121 0.712% 0.62850 4.043% 1.46950 0.34392 0%275 0.70196 0.185% 0.6492 0.92490 0.83576 0.05502 0.59014 1.11236 0.%932 0.79281 1.65080 4.283(B 4.71542 4 .6%14 4.63924 0.04310 4.81353 -1 .47168 0.02482 4.95472 4.82935 4.85765 4.95703 4 .7%07 4.81%2 4.88211 0.02448 2.557% 1.81579 1.965% 1.82577 1.44416 1.59032 Robust Std Err 8.3182 0.61732 1.21165 0.762% 0.50706 0.50%8 0.48501 1.068% 1 .00276 0.35987 0.36401 0.46983 0.%%4 0.65992 1 .04598 1.03815 0.088% 0.16265 0.05520 0%367 0.15399 0.14517 0.14413 0.08323 0.04542 0.05181 1.%417 0.37513 0.75204 0.7%67 1.02733 1.17594 1.32590 1.58149 1 .57326 1.73074 1.77853 1.88462 1.81421 1 .86341 2.02749 2.11519 2.%729 0.47756 0.46311 0.672% 1.15895 3.95%0 2.85928 Robust t-stat 4 .93764 2.25791 0.03441 2.%655 0.48410 2.38%2 0.44528 0.01441 1 .1823 0.73240 2.2541 1 4 .47337 4 .2631 1 2.79238 0.37659 0.00240 4 .4824 0.21463 2.16134 1 .921 % 4 .021 19 0.06743 0.63971 1 .93610 0.7524 0.13455 2.23241 4 .94650 4 .9258 0.21% 0.%861 0.6822 0.34812 4 .79396 0.68247 0.47134 0.34431 0.294% 0.54901 0.29144 0.1%95 0.24625 0.52399 4.151 16 3.27846 2.76428 2.4230 1 .86570 2.14512 Tabb 8.12 - Industry Lag 14, PHS Lag 20 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 90.83429 Sum of Sqr Resid 131 .57881 R-Squared 0.76664 Sigma Squared 0.81429 Parameter one 43.25281 curird 1 .53099 lg1ird 0.52755 19de 1 .54559 lg3ird 0.2991 1 lg4ird 1 .19621 lgSird -1 .59851 lg6ird 0.07934 lgTird 1 .27504 Igeird 0.99498 ngird 0.75558 lg10ird 0.71985 lg1 1ird -1 .04268 lg12ird 1 .55646 lg13ird 0.16055 Ig14ird 0.06735 curreg 0.10799 lagreg1 0.16713 lagreg2 0.17005 lagregS 0.02772 lagreg4 0.1 1083 lagregS 0.17732 lagregG 0.28141 lagreg7 0.09461 lagregB 1 .63038 lagregQ 0.53695 PHS 20 -1 .1 1344 y79 4 .31782 y80 -1 .71974 y81 0.65581 y82 0.59026 y83 0.26236 y84 0.58942 y85 0.69891 y86 0.63858 y87 0.79473 y88 4.09076 y89 0.72420 y90 0.92292 y91 4.18404 y92 4.62526 y93 1 .62135 y94 1 .17360 cns 1 .441 13 car 2.498% ant 5.64062 giu 4.86635 der 7.38611 res 6.13349 155 Estimate Poisson Std Err 10.03849 0.94410 1.33%5 1.28736 1.30127 1.26402 1.28582 1.32678 1.2%27 1.24845 1.12858 1.10261 1.%%4 1.%478 0.18127 0.18440 0.18%4 0.193% 0.186% 0.17585 0.15455 0.14534 0.14138 0.13770 1.263% 0.54990 0.%4% 1.04192 1.32695 1.58786 1.78136 1.96933 2.15845 2.31025 2.41646 2.5%67 2.57070 2.%451 2.67%3 2.72711 2.7%86 0.72937 0.71539 0.91119 1.55845 4.95643 3.72179 5.11447 3.85676 Poisson t-stat 4.32020 1.62163 4.88770 1.21159 0.2986 0.94635 4.24318 0.059% 0.98%6 0.79698 0.%950 0.65286 0.94958 1 .42171 0.88570 0.36526 0.5%46 0.86293 0.91%9 0.15762 0.71711 1.2%2 4.99044 0.68708 1.29%6 0.97644 4.38375 4.26480 4 .29%1 4.67257 4.454% 4.14879 4 .%296 4 .%1% 4.50575 4.51385 4.59130 4.42991 4.46436 4.53424 4.65373 2.2294 1.84050 1.58159 1.%293 1.13%4 1.30753 1.44416 1.59032 Robust Std Err 9.6%17 0.42105 1 .03%6 0.74496 0.43503 0.48578 0.6%73 1 .1 2551 0.96059 0.37470 0.2%88 0.48519 0.94429 0.59145 0.12646 0.18161 0.057 46 0.08989 0. 1 5254 0.13796 0.12405 0.%526 0.05250 0.042% 1 .15563 0.38395 0.82843 0.90749 1 .27345 1 .4%28 1 .65556 1 .95984 1 9%51 2.21879 2. 32786 2.48762 2.42938 2.45295 2.61353 2.65734 2.64491 0.56739 0.561 31 0.7%37 1 .45539 4.78334 3.53034 3.95%0 2.85928 Robust t-stat 4 .38%4 3.63610 0.43277 2.07473 0.68756 2.56819 0.39753 0.07049 1.32735 0.65540 2.83117 4.483% 4.10420 2.63162 4.26953 0.37086 1.87931 1.85918 4.11477 0.20%2 0.%345 1.86150 -5.3%50 0.2075 1.41081 4.39848 4.34403 4.45216 4.35045 4.79413 4.56458 4.15436 4 .79%5 4 .%7% 4.56306 4.52545 4.68387 4.51825 4.50100 4.57452 4.74874 2.85759 2.%083 1.8%47 1.71644 1.1792 1.37843 1.86570 2.14512 156 Table 8.13 - Mushy L89 12, PHS Nested 12,17,22 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 92.15151 Sum of Sqr Resid 124.23083 R-Squared 0.77967 Sigma Squared 0.81582 Parameter Estimate one 4 6.57264 curird 1 .13937 lg1ird 0.40982 ngird 1 .85343 lgSird 0.22204 lg4‘rd 1 .1 1641 lg5ird 4 .77030 lgGird 0.21469 lg7ird 1 .13635 lg8ird 4 .16502 ngird 0.70150 lg10ird 0.72865 lg1 1 ird 4 .16079 Ig12ird 1 .76550 curreg 0.12725 lagreg1 0.06401 lagregZ 0.08524 lagreg3 0.17551 lagreg4 0.15880 13ng 0.03691 lagregG 0.10397 lagreg7 0.16160 lagreg8 0.30104 lagregQ 0.10120 PHS 12 0.46237 PHS 17 2.40%5 PHS 22 0.44051 y79 0.74499 y80 4 .46200 y81 4 .71579 y82 0.07712 y83 0.10084 y84 0.18227 y85 0.881 16 y86 4.15232 y87 4.14191 y88 4.00751 y89 4.14820 y90 4.43738 y91 4.09781 y92 4.31263 y93 4.71883 y94 0.15364 cns 2.06859 car 1 .69323 ant 1 .90766 giu 2.83321 der 7.77298 res 6.51756 PoissonStdErr 9.50335 1.00743 1.34115 1.32996 1.3249 1.27144 12% 1.34506 1.285% 1.24347 1.11534 1.10284 1.%275 1.10705 0.183% 0.18304 0.181% 0.19375 0.1%91 0.17765 0.15356 0.14445 0.14515 0.14%9 1.31245 1.48615 0.81856 0.53886 0.750% 0.92%7 1.14588 1.404% 1.61743 1.%370 1.95261 2.04427 2.11345 2.21075 2.3%93 2.34751 2.42145 2.51435 2.57437 0.77300 0.%830 0.92714 1.43718 4.68430 3.43154 Poisson t—sut 4 .74387 1 .13%7 4 .79682 1 393% 0.16790 0.878% 4 .36513 0.15961 0.88432 0.93691 0.62896 0.6%70 4 .0626 1 .59477 0.%230 0.34973 0.46941 0.905% 0.83617 0.20774 0.677% 1 .1 1873 0.074% 0.7237 0.3529 1 .62053 0.53815 4 .38253 4 .94762 4 .86302 4 .81268 0.20750 4 .96749 4 .59736 0.12655 0.0261 1 4 .%619 4 .87%8 4 92%4 4 .745% 4 .78101 4 .87676 0.%190 2.67%5 1 .95” 2.05758 1 .97136 1 .65937 1 .%931 RobustStd Err 7.02428 0.57614 1 .%937 0.77%2 0.43465 0.43303 0.71762 1.1% 0.98346 0.37%8 0.2512 0.52%7 0.%825 0.647% 0.116% 0.1682 0.04404 0.%853 0.153% 0.14424 0.124% 0.%011 0.05981 0.05390 0.677% 0.928(5 0.47659 0.316% 0.%041 0.74425 0.%591 1 .14328 1 32% 1 .61648 1 .65633 1.72116 1 .77050 1.91374 1 .8%30 1 .9%44 2.07542 2.191% 2.17501 0.38270 0.38627 0.49541 1 .02323 3.27776 2.52827 Robust t-stat 0.35934 1 977% 0.38744 2.3823 0.51%6 2.57812 0.4%91 0.18495 1 .15546 0.%529 3. 1 1612 4 .39%3 4 .2928 2.72860 4 .%858 0.38053 1 .93536 1 .78120 4 .%1% 0.25587 0.83424 2.01706 0.03323 4 .87753 0.%295 2.%%7 0.92429 0.35%8 0.1 1757 0.30540 0.1%% 0.7123 0.40700 4 782% 0.50694 0.4%47 0.2%49 0.16759 0.41254 0.14720 0.07795 0.1 5371 0.36947 5.40530 4.3%57 3.85%4 2.7%% 2.37143 2. 57788 157 Tabb 8.14 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Maud 9.17.25 Num of Obs 119 Log Likeiihood 92.12054 Sum of Sqr Resid 125.45063 R-Squared 0.77751 Sigma Squared 0.81991 Parameter Estimate one 4 6.02741 curird 1 .07396 lg1ird 0.36723 ngird 1 .80779 lg3ird 0.14869 ig4ird 1 .1 1822 I95ird 4 .78944 igGird 0.30525 Ig7ird 1 .0732 l98ird 4 .18800 IgQird 0.7128 lg10ird 0.74095 Ig1 1ird 4 .16099 lg12ird 1 .75856 curreg 0.13137 lagreg1 0.06604 lagregZ 0.08279 lagregS 0.17849 lagreg4 0.16472 lagregS 0.04074 lagregG 0.1 1 156 lagreg7 0.16105 lagregB 0.30506 lagregQ 0.10979 PHS 9 0.07222 PHS 17 2.07199 PHS 25 0.21326 y79 0.63680 y80 4 .24188 y81 4 .37886 y82 4 .63409 y83 0.56302 y84 0.57929 y85 0.21574 y86 0.45283 y87 0.44877 y88 0.32858 y89 0.44767 y90 0.72268 y91 0.39616 y92 0.62138 y93 4.01339 y94 4.42852 cns 2.0851 1 car 1 .76651 ant 1 .94580 giu 2.67696 der 7.51364 6.15821 Poisson Std Err 10.17516 0.%299 1.33659 1.32527 1.30439 1.27%6 1.30336 1.32584 1.2%19 1.24768 1.11994 1.103% 1.%057 1.11336 0.18405 0.18293 0.181% 0.19373 0.18%4 0.17%9 0.15327 0.14377 0.14319 0.13796 1.33287 1.19470 0.40442 0.52583 0.7%51 0.%271 0.90537 1.07664 1.2854 1.3%18 1.405% 1.45725 1.49764 1.550% 1.61065 1.66339 1.75142 1.85350 1.91478 0.95%9 1.%858 1.10296 1.41714 5.23746 3.48463 Poisson t-stat 4 .57515 1 .%154 4 .771% 1 .36410 0.11399 0.8%44 4 .37295 0.23023 0.83833 0.95217 0.636% 0.6712 4 .%457 1 .57951 0.71378 0.361% 0.45727 0.92136 0.87177 0.23134 0.72783 1 .12019 0.13053 0.79581 0.05418 1 .73432 0.52732 4 .21 1% 4 .75%2 4 .71775 4 .%4% 0.38058 0.%948 4 .69246 0.45748 0.36663 0.2255 0.2417 0.31 129 0.04171 0.%769 0.16530 0.31281 2.19279 1 .6277 1 .76416 1 .88%9 1 .43459 1 .76725 RobustStd Err 4.69136 0.632% 1 048% 0.82163 0.4%28 0.44925 0.77816 1 .18%7 1 .(XBOB 0.39466 0.%%1 0.50838 0.8%% 0.707% 0.121% 0.16744 0.05255 0.10%5 0.155% 0.14767 0.12597 . 0.07599 0.05521 0.04581 0.66274 0.73637 0.19431 0.26652 0.5%28 0.59267 0.59969 0.69953 0.70532 0.93731 0.90468 0.8852 0.92965 0.97414 0.84%1 0.918% 1 .%593 1.18670 1.14341 0.45870 0.49478 0.39674 0.62679 2.43%2 1 .71976 Robust t—stat 0.41637 1 .%717 0.258% 2.2%26 0.303% 2.4%08 0.29957 0.25848 1 .06674 0.01020 3.%673 4 .45746 4 3%32 2.487% 4 .07%0 0.39440 1 .57 544 1 .66%9 4 .%271 0.27586 0.88559 2.1 1942 0.52586 0.39688 0.1%97 2.81378 1 .%749 0.3%26 0.10746 0.32652 0.72488 0.66394 0.65689 0.36393 0.81662 0.%593 0.5%47 0.53919 4.38523 0.69712 0.39739 0.38198 0.87309 4.54570 3.57029 4.90450 4.27%0 3.0%73 3.5%85 158 Tabb 8.15 - industry Lao 14, PHS W 12,17,22 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 92.37649 Sum of Sqr Resid 124.95949 R-Squared 0.77838 Sigma Squared 0.82629 Parameter Estimate one 4 7.95168 curird 1 .15163 lg1ird 0.47335 ngrd 1 .85827 Ig3ird 0.26457 Ig4ird 1 .19932 lg5ird 4 .86090 Igeird 0.24814 Ig7ird 1 .19762 lgaird 4 .13653 ngird 0.65821 lg10ird 0.74107 lg1 1ird 4 .17209 lg12ird 1 .76555 Ig13ird 0.24360 lg14ird 0.25846 curreg 0.1 1868 lagreg1 0.04694 lagregZ 0.08339 lagreg3 0.17266 lagreg4 0.14569 lagreg5 0.02464 lagregG 0.1 1566 lagreg7 0.14626 lagreg8 0.30533 lagregQ 0.09225 PHS 14 4.28591 PHS 17 3.48370 HPS 22 0.39480 y79 0.85907 y80 4 .65125 y81 4 .96712 y82 0.35278 y83 0.42796 y84 0.61752 y85 0.39579 y86 4.70549 y87 4.66845 y88 4.56161 y89 4.73950 y90 4.9425 y91 4.61647 y92 4.83989 y93 0.28134 y94 -5.70191 cns 2.17936 car 1 .79238 ant 2.01445 giu 3.05981 der 8.57090 res 7.20723 PoissonStdErr 9.74869 1.02342 1.37212 1.34629 1.34586 1.30794 1.33045 1.35371 1.292% 1.26950 1.15877 1.10587 1 .%368 1.26378 1.16387 0.97233 0.18823 0.18468 0.18152 0.19566 0.1925 0.1%16 0.15592 0.14618 0.14828 0.14178 1.75187 2.30255 0.84338 0.56681 0.81391 1113911 1.21746 1.477% 1.74462 1.96870 2.11167 2.19467 2.28291 2.37393 2.4%63 2.46242 2.538% 2.64513 2.68776 0.754% 0.%314 0.%4% 1.47717 4.81120 3.65840 Poisson t-stat 4 .84145 1 .12527 4 .%258 1 .3%29 0.19658 0.91%5 4 .39870 0.183% 0.92688 0.%526 0.56802 0.67012 4 .07169 1 .39704 0.20%0 0.26582 0.63051 0.25417 0.45938 0.88243 0.75779 0.13675 0.741% 1 .%053 0.05914 0.65%7 0.73402 1 .51297 0.46812 4 .51562 0.02879 4 .94937 4 .93253 0.320% 0.07353 4 724% 0.2832 0.12717 4 .9%15 4 .9%47 0.05104 4 .87476 4 .9%30 4 .99663 0.12144 2.88137 211383 2.25256 2.07141 1 .78145 1 .97%5 RobustStd Err 6.92910 0.642% 1.1%44 0.78644 0.48%5 0.48857 0.53133 1.12336 0.95179 0.36677 0.39691 0.48125 0.89938 0.64959 1.07948 1.02633 0.08641 0.15535 0.%965 0.10142 0.15294 0.15%4 0.14181 0.0%59 0.04513 0.06236 0.97279 1.15875 0.53669 0.35647 0.73282 0.75448 1.%266 1.15%3 1.44641 1.7(1155 1.76856 1.87512 1.90585 2.%294 1.97356 2.%445 2.27391 2.3682 2.335% 0.3%16 0.25323 0.53307 1.%591 3.20187 2.42966 7.07795 3.77%6 2.95373 2.67684 2.96636 159 Table 8.16 - Nutty Log 14, PHS Nested 9.17.25 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 92.13606 Sum of Sqr Resid 1 26.2564 R-Squared 0.77608 Sigma Squared 0.84255 Parameter Estimate one 4 5.98923 curird 1 .10184 191 ird 0.39060 ig2ird 1 .77544 lg3ird 0.14984 lg4ird 1 .16995 lgSird 4 .82862 lgSird 0.3121 1 lg7ird 1 .071 56 lgBird 4 .16074 ngird 0.7031 5 191 Oird 0.74939 lg11ird 4.17814 lg12ird 1 .84772 191 3ird 0. 1 9959 Ig14ird 0.1 2063 curreg 0.13730 lagreg1 0.06244 lagreg2 0.08284 lagregS 0.18100 lagreg4 0.16564 lagreg5 0.03763 lagreg6 0.1 1471 lagreg7 0.1 5899 lagre98 0.30772 IagregQ 0.10689 PHS 9 0.07550 PHS 17 2.07086 PHS 25 0.21061 y79 0.63479 y80 4 .2361 1 y81 4 .38103 y82 4 .63709 y83 0.56339 y84 0.56919 y85 0. 20694 y86 0.45776 y87 0.43%5 y88 0.3%29 y89 0.45147 y90 0.71842 y91 0.38864 y92 0.60981 y93 0.99999 y94 4.42214 cns 2.08676 car 1 .77052 ant 1.94693 giu 2.67246 der 7.50740 res 6.1 5053 Poisson Std Err 10.63423 1.%852 1.36%1 1.34458 1.33688 1.30381 1.33742 1.32736 1.28%7 1.27539 1.1%21 1.1%12 1.%929 1.26438 1.17183 0.9729 0.18747 0.18472 0.181% 0.19529 0.1%% 0.17773 0.15475 0.14420 0.146% 0.13982 1.351% 1.39086 0.41851 0.53%? 0.75403 0.%3% 0.99790 1.155% 1.32073 1.44124 1.51079 1.54492 1.%567 1.64371 1.67290 1.71274 1.8%54 1.91470 1.96581 0.96310 1.15833 1.10794 1.47513 5.47754 3.73420 Poisson t-stat 4 .5%56 1.%253 4.74750 1.32044 0.112% 0.%733 4.36727 0.23514 0.83515 0.91011 0.%139 0.67627 4.07173 1.46136 0.17%3 0.12406 0.73240 0.33%1 0.45748 0.92684 0.87325 0.21172 0.74126 1.10257 0.10634 0.76446 0.05586 1.48%1 0.50323 4.18218 4.63934 4.54598 4.64054 0.21921 4.94528 4.53127 0.28871 0.2%0 0.06101 0.%981 0.2274 4.97849 0.%484 0.%910 0.24952 2.16671 1.52851 1.75726 1.81167 1.37058 1.647% Robust Std Err 4.11581 0.72101 1.23494 0.83412 0.58%3 0.53218 0.%7% 1.13546 1.01361 0.40307 0.3%55 0.45704 0.%193 0.%172 1.173% 1.01527 0.09035 0.15%0 0.05455 0.11279 0.15113 0.15772 0.14884 0.%435 0.044% 0.05496 0.59764 0.54243 0.2338 0.26211 0.54637 0.53749 0.46779 0.55846 0.56841 0.78282 0.71854 0.75850 0.79617 0.79648 0.67439 0.77353 0.92927 1.05239 0.98106 0.46304 0.52882 0.3%61 0.54867 2.27796 1.5262 Robust t-stat 0.88483 1.52819 4.93581 2.12852 0.25820 2.19839 0.0%58 0.27488 1.05716 0.87978 1.90272 4.63965 4.320% 2.67119 0.17011 0.11881 4.51972 0.41542 1.51851 1.%473 4 .%%0 0.23858 0.77065 2.47064 0.99341 4.94468 0.12634 3.81772 0.942% 0.42185 0.26241 0.5%41 0.49963 4.59%8 4.51993 0.81920 4.8123 4.52334 4.15651 4.33339 -5.51375 4.3%74 0.88459 0.8%87 4.50749 4.50663 3.348% 4.%716 4.87083 3.29567 4.03944 160 Table 8.17 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 15 (10% Depreciation) Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 90.95091 Sum of Sqr Resid 128.9766 R-Squared 0.77126 Sigma Squared 0.83023 Parameter Estimate one 4 0.91476 curird 1 .15814 Ig1ird 0.32845 ngird 1 .67713 IgBird 0.09544 lg4ird 1 .10505 lgSird 4.78012 lgGird 0.26553 lg7ird 1 .06561 lgBird 4.10441 ngird 0.68592 Ig10ird 0.76637 Ig11ird 4.14414 ig12ird 1.78099 cu rreg 0.16976 lagreg1 0.09002 lagreg2 0.06449 lagreg3 0.15772 lagreg4 0.20236 lagregS 0.06025 lagreg6 0.13094 lagreg7 0.16903 IagregB 0.30930 iagregQ 0.12142 PHS 1 5 1 .50200 y79 0.40782 y80 0.77840 y81 0.76025 y82 0.90072 y83 4 .65155 y84 4 .44064 y85 0.89868 y86 0.03542 y87 4 .98985 y88 4 .80748 y89 4 .89399 y90 0.15773 y91 4 .84184 y92 0.00666 y93 0.26822 y94 0.71248 cns 1 .6238 car 1 .34781 ant 1 .33773 giu 1 .86643 der 4.44264 res 3.79072 Poisson Std Err 7.94731 0.96259 1.32797 1.29882 1.29564 1.26067 1.29367 1.31745 1.28613 1.25807 1.13208 1.11497 1.10908 1.12820 0.18204 0.18279 0.18006 0.19226 0.18605 0.17424 0.15097 0.14360 0.13941 0.13700 1.06714 0.49536 0.60383 0.64508 0.72684 0.85416 0.92523 0.94193 0.99763 1.03770 1.04904 1.08616 1.13803 1.20387 1.26566 1.32396 1.41052 0.68044 0.77935 0.77427 1.12456 3.78859 2.69852 4.37339 1.20314 4.75339 1.29127 0.07367 0.87655 4.37603 0.20155 0.82854 0.87786 0.60589 0.68734 4.03162 1.57861 0.93251 0.49246 0.35815 0.82035 4 .08766 0.34580 0.86733 1.17709 0.21859 0.88626 1.40751 0.82328 4.28912 4.17854 4.23922 4.93355 4.55706 0.95408 0.04027 4.91756 4.72298 4.74375 4 .89603 4.52994 4.58547 4.71321 4.92303 2.38429 1.72940 1.72773 1.65970 1.17263 1.40474 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err 3.66732 0.57500 1 . 12025 0.74274 0.55878 0.45044 0.76228 1 .21405 1 .08098 0.42079 0.21813 0.50874 0.93813 0.66474 0.12195 0.17520 0.04317 0.09996 0.15326 0.13038 0.12291 0.08149 0.04212 0.03838 0.39970 0.23495 0.47007 0.40540 0.35122 0.50959 0.33684 0.59504 0.48478 0.52424 0.61960 0.58077 0.48888 0.53230 0.64062 0.78134 0.74126 0.24671 0.30372 0.20742 0.50547 1 .66626 1 .23895 Robust t-stet 0.97622 2.01415 0.07851 2.25803 0.17081 2.45324 0.33526 0.21872 0.98578 0.62462 3.14454 4 .50640 4 .21960 2.67924 4 .39201 0.51378 1 .49388 1 .57790 4 .32032 0.46212 4 .06528 2.07416 ~7.34401 0.16357 3.75780 4 .73579 4 .65593 4 .87533 0.56451 0.24093 4.27688 -1 .51028 4.19864 0.79570 0.91717 0.261 14 4.41361 0.46014 0.13236 0.90298 0.65927 6.57602 4.43768 6.44932 3.69250 2.66624 3.05963 161 Table 8.18 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 16 (10% Depreciation) Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 91 .27322 Sum of Sqr Redd 127.83786 R-Squared 0.77328 Sigma Squared 0.82032 Parameter Estimate one 4 3.1 3581 curird 1 .1 1907 Ig1ird 0.36109 ngird 1 .77761 lg3ird 0.09465 lg4ird 1 .08091 lgSird 4 .7771 1 lgGird 0.27264 lg7ird 1.11118 lgBird 4.16437 IgQird 0.70596 lg10ird 0.77219 lg11ird 4.15649 Ig12ird 1.78001 curreg 0.16109 lagreg1 0.08236 lagreg2 0.06975 IagregB 0.16652 lagreg4 0.19178 lagregS 0.05527 lagre96 0.12773 lagreg7 0.16285 lagreg8 0.31000 lagregQ 0.1 1905 PHS 16 1.86008 y79 0. 50887 y80 4 .00585 y81 4 .03783 y82 4 .23492 y83 0.06714 y84 4 .94308 y85 4 .46641 y86 0.62191 y87 0.57925 y88 0.43209 y89 0.50734 y90 0.79801 y91 0.44181 y92 0.69251 y93 0.96370 y94 0.40410 cns 1 .821 90 car 1 .52922 ant 1 .56725 giu 2.17316 der 5.68148 res 4.77353 Poisson Std Err 8.35885 0.96557 1.33056 1.30729 1.29974 1.26254 1.29381 1.31818 1.27986 1.25321 1.12726 1.11060 1.10171 1.12077 0.18212 0.18276 0.18003 0.19281 0.18631 0.17486 0.15100 0.14373 0.13941 0.13683 1.14088 0.50929 0.66071 0.72465 0.82880 0.98588 1.09739 1.14785 1.20717 1.24374 1.27253 1.30038 1.35956 1.39845 1.49846 1.55677 1.63369 0.71588 0.79324 0.81353 1.18360 4.04225 2.93894 Poisson t-stat 4.57149 1.15897 4.77450 1.35977 0.07282 0.85614 4.37355 0.20683 0.86821 0.92912 0.62626 0.69529 4.04973 1.58820 0.88449 0.45063 0.38742 0.86364 4.02935 0.31610 0.84590 1.13307 0.22370 0.87007 1.63038 0.99919 4.52238 4.43217 4.49001 0.09674 4.77063 4.27753 0.17195 0.07378 4.91 123 4.92816 0.05803 4.74608 4.79686 4.90375 0.08369 2.54498 1.92781 1.92647 1.83606 1.40552 1.62423 Robust Std Err 4.49612 0.58642 1.09730 0.75981 0.55053 0.43400 0.74531 1.20209 1.06256 0.39961 0.22533 0.52706 0.92793 0.66663 0.12142 0.17373 0.04049 0.09771 0.15453 0.13286 0.1 1932 0.08212 0.04275 0.03955 0.51878 0.24487 0.52008 0.47048 0.45151 0.57869 0.49576 0.74824 0.66248 0.67519 0.77077 0.76094 0.64931 0.70529 0.85161 0.98609 0.94740 0.29438 0.34663 0.28488 0.59749 2.09785 1.55770 Robust t—stat 0.92159 1.90829 0.15173 2.33956 0.17192 2.49056 0.38439 0.22680 1.04576 0.91377 3.13302 4.46510 4.24632 2.67016 4.32674 0.47405 1.7274 1.70417 4.24105 0.41601 4.07044 1.98313 -7.25115 0.01024 3.58550 0.07817 4.93402 0.20590 0.73508 0.57211 0.91936 4.95981 0.95775 0.82005 0.15541 0.29507 4.30917 0.46215 0.16167 0.00550 0.59310 6.18884 4.41162 5.50135 3.63713 2.70824 3.06447 162 Table 8.19 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 17 (10% Depreciation) Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R-Squared Sigma Squared Parameter one curird lg1 ird ngird Ig3ird lg4ird lgSird lgSird lg7ird lgBird ngird lg10wd Ig1 1ird Ig12wd curreg lagreg1 lagreg2 lagregB lagreg4 IagregS lagreg6 lagreg7 IagregB lagregQ PHS 17 y79 y80 y81 y82 y83 y84 y85 y86 y87 y88 y89 y90 y91 y92 y93 y94 one car ant giu der res 119 92.02087 123.94608 0.78018 0.80159 Estimate 47.92620 1.05714 0.34999 1.86026 0.11775 1.08890 4.80206 0.28072 1.08680 4.17647 0.73812 0.74629 4.15571 1.76650 0.13171 0.06521 0.07908 0.17432 0.16816 0.04064 0.11054 0.15749 0.31529 0.11536 2.57085 0.73340 4.43028 4.63346 4.91719 0.88038 0.91798 0.56219 0.80895 0.80041 0.68455 0.81694 4.10515 0.78834 4.01869 4.41857 4.86673 2.20918 1.88761 2.03364 2.84938 8.23793 6.75882 Poisson Std Err 9.19330 0.97031 1.33203 1.31372 1.30104 1.26601 1.29154 1.32239 1.27718 1.24438 1.11571 1.10341 1.09086 1.10893 0.18349 0.18299 0.17954 0.19320 0.18787 0.17582 0.15203 0.14375 0.13997 0.13665 1.25760 0.53764 0.74282 0.86661 0.99205 1.18263 1.34872 1.44527 1.53507 1.57974 1.61929 1.66785 1.71600 1.76573 1.84129 1.94920 2.01969 0.76896 0.82001 0.88307 1.30609 4.48470 3.32466 4.94992 1.08948 4.76422 1.41603 0.09050 0.8601 1 4.39528 0.21228 0.85094 0.94543 0.66157 0.67635 4.05945 1.59297 0.71783 0.35634 0.44047 0.90230 0.89508 0.231 16 0.72710 1.09563 0.25253 0.84418 2.04426 4.36412 4.92547 4.88490 4.93255 0.43557 0.16351 4.77281 0.48129 0.40573 0.27541 0.28854 0.39229 0.14548 0.18254 0.26686 0.40964 2.87295 2.30193 2.30292 2.18161 1.83689 2.03293 Poisson t—stat Robust Std Err 6.22171 0.59540 1.03860 0.78162 0.50765 0.42978 0.75055 1.17084 1.02858 0.39135 0.21789 0.52927 0.90620 0.67135 0.11808 0.17009 0.03730 0.09756 0.15538 0.13520 0.12024 0.08028 0.04389 0.03791 0.76250 0.27794 0.59404 0.61760 0.64471 0.76539 0.79143 1 .05849 1 .03062 1.01468 1.10939 1.13549 1.04374 1.12123 1.26514 1 .43076 1.41573 0.40979 0.45198 0.45491 0.81 1 17 2.94873 2.19678 Robust t-stat 0.88123 1.77552 0.26265 2.38000 0.23194 2.53360 0.40099 0.23976 1 .05660 0.00615 3.38761 4.41004 4 .27533 2.63127 4 .1 1549 0.38336 2.1 1994 1.78673 4 .08227 0.30061 0.91933 1.96172 -7. 18286 0.04272 3.37160 0.63867 0.40771 0.64485 0.97374 0.76330 0.68698 0.42060 0.69580 0.74542 0.32125 0.36148 0.93312 0.37873 0.17648 0.08826 0.43760 5.39106 4.17635 4.47038 3.51266 2.79372 3.07669 163 Table 8.20 -lndus1ry Leg 12, PHS Lag 18 (10% Depreciation) Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R-Squared Sigma Squared Parameter one curird lg1 ird lg2ird Ig3ird lg4ird IgSird Ig6ird Ig7ird lgBird lg9ird lg1 Oird Ig11kd Ig120d cu rreg lagreg1 lagreg2 lagregS lagreg4 IagregS lagreg6 lagreg7 lagregB iagregQ PHS 1 8 y79 y80 y81 y82 y83 y84 y85 y86 y87 y88 y89 y90 y91 y92 y93 y94 cns car ant giu der res 119 91.86941 124.87125 0.77854 0.79892 Estimate 4 9.52824 1.27215 0.55308 1.84067 0.23537 1.10546 4.72034 0.07425 1.22581 4.14997 0.78619 0.73152 4.09419 1.63519 0.11973 0.04169 0.09924 0.17302 0.15230 0.01950 .0.10249 0.16390 0.30528 0.11456 2.71591 0.80041 4.59192 4.90134 0.33254 0.31322 0.39997 0.17506 4.50647 4.58421 4.49658 4.65301 4.99556 4.64545 4.91479 0.24417 0.78203 2.25807 1.87502 2.14925 3.15569 8.98716 7.40153 Poisson Std Err 10.26496 0.95653 1.33879 1.30885 1.30215 1.26308 1.28617 1.31914 1.28113 1.24311 1.11444 1.09316 1.08759 1.09549 0.18400 0.18483 0.18083 0.19296 0.18839 0.17675 0.15302 0.14422 0.14016 0.13690 1.39315 0.56416 0.82398 1.01880 1.22240 1.42655 1.62934 1.79958 1.93171 2.01957 2.07627 2.13918 2.21090 2.24524 2.33918 2.41406 2.52297 0.82200 0.84618 0.97812 1.47045 5.03945 3.79242 4 .90242 1.32996 4.90700 1 .40633 0.18075 0.87521 4.33757 0.05629 0.95682 0.92508 0.70546 0.66918 4 .00607 1 .49265 0.65074 0.22559 0.54880 0.89662 0.80841 0.11033 0.66979 1.13652 0.17818 0.83685 1.94948 4.41877 4.93198 4.86624 4.90817 0.32253 0.08671 4.76434 0.33289 0.26989 0.16570 0.17514 0.25951 0.06902 0.10107 0.17234 0.29175 2.74704 2.21588 2.19733 2.14607 1.78336 1.95166 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err 8.48044 0.50885 0.99253 0.79105 0.45338 0.45065 0.73083 1.11417 0.99074 0.38482 0.25863 0.53225 0.92102 0.63825 0.1 1706 0.17585 0.04288 0.09693 0.15408 0.14016 0.12319 0.08595 0.04652 0.03199 1.03097 0.33469 0.72313 0.76432 0.95173 1.04155 1.19487 1 .47834 1.49619 1.53991 1.61719 1 .71720 1.64028 1.71440 1.89915 1.99825 2.00806 0.49591 0.53816 0.66632 1.10965 3.96852 2.92295 Robust t-stat 0.30274 2.50004 0.57229 2.32688 0.51914 2.45304 0.35397 0.06664 1 .23726 0.98831 3.03987 4 .37440 4 .18802 2.56201 4 .02283 0.2371 1 2.31462 1 .78499 0.98846 0.13913 0.83203 1 .90697 0.56252 0.58124 2.63432 0.39150 0.20142 0.48760 0.45085 0.18103 0.84547 0.14772 0.01 196 0.97694 0.78049 0.70965 0.04555 0.70966 0.58788 0.62438 0.87941 4.55336 3.48415 3.22556 2.84387 2.26461 2.53221 164 Table 8.21 - Industry Lag 12. PHS Lag 19 (10% Depreciation) Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 91 .49206 Sum of Sqr Resid 128.31454 R0quared 0.77243 Sigma Squared 0.80293 Parameter Estimate one 4 8.48680 curird 1 .45076 lg1ird 0.52730 ngird 1 .58924 lg3ird 0.35322 lg4ird 1 .15253 IgSird 4.61858 lgGird 0.06387 Ig7ird 1 .24704 lg8ird 4 .03344 ngird 0.75256 lg10ird 0.67003 lg11ird 4.07854 Ig12ird 1.58153 curreg 0. 13069 lagreg1 0.04305 lagreg2 0.12032 lagreg3 0. 17069 lagreg4 0.15378 lagreg5 0.01285 lagreg6 0.08942 lagreg7 0.16854 lagregB 0.28138 lagregQ 0.10040 PHS 19 2.40882 y79 0.73779 y80 4 .4821 0 y81 4 .81409 y82 0.29579 y83 0.32898 y84 0.34442 y85 0.14609 y86 4.541 1 5 y87 4.68400 y88 4.65444 y89 4.82310 y90 -5. 17207 y91 4.85263 y92 0.08082 y93 -5.43146 y94 -5.87297 cns 2.05001 car 1 .61527 ant 1.9741 1 giu 3.12039 der 8.24732 res 6.87557 Poisson Std Err 10.84420 0.94811 1.33912 1.29063 1.30255 1.26425 1.28280 1.32366 1.28452 1.24463 1.11714 1.09604 1.08724 1.09360 0.18316 0.18531 0.18411 0.19330 0.18774 0.17691 0.15548 0.14461 0.14101 0.13697 1.40569 0.57028 0.84504 1.08676 1.34864 1.60526 1.79679 2.01010 2.19396 2.32883 2.42715 2.50425 2.58633 2.64042 2.71870 2.81162 2.87167 0.80798 0.80632 1.00255 1.59596 5.27601 3.99614 4.70476 1.53017 4.88728 1.23137 0.27117 0.91163 4.26175 0.04825 0.97082 0.83032 0.67365 0.61132 43.99200 1.44617 -o.71353 0.23230 0.65353 0.88302 0.81910 0.07265 0.57514 1.16547 4.99541 4.73300 1.71363 4.29374 4.75388 4.66927 4.70230 0.07380 4.86133 4.56514 0.06984 -2.01131 4.91766 4.92597 4.99978 4.83782 4.86884 4.93179 2.04514 2.53720 2.00326 1.96910 1.95518 1.56317 1.72055 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err 9.90491 0.42888 0.99643 0.73368 0.41514 0.43644 0.66675 1.09165 0.97572 0.37187 0.25373 0.47688 0.89161 0.60349 0.12190 0.17974 0.05515 0.09446 0.15628 0.14373 0.12700 0.09142 0.05417 0.03737 1.17855 0.37871 0.81110 0.88043 1.17262 1.34703 1.51402 1.83188 1.86686 2.02614 2.13228 2.26403 2.20720 2.27510 2.45248 2.55165 2.51288 0.55505 0.57592 0.78995 1.37031 4.67835 3.45119 Robust t-stat 4.86643 3.38266 0.53635 2.16613 0.85084 2.64077 0.42759 0.05851 1.27808 0.77901 2.96596 4.40503 4.20966 2.62066 4.07206 0.23951 2.18167 1.80698 0.98401 0.08942 0.70411 1.84369 0.19477 0.68696 2.04388 4.94819 4.82727 0.06044 4.95782 0.47135 0.20897 4.71741 0.43251 0.31179 0.18285 0.13032 0.34327 0.13293 0.07171 0.12861 0.33715 3.69334 2.80468 2.49902 2.27715 1.76287 1.99223 165 Table 8.22 - Industry Log 12, PHS Log 20 (10% Doptochtion) Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R-Squared Sigma Squared Parameter one curird Ig1 ird igZird lgBird Ig4ird lgSird I96ird Ig7ird igBird ngird lg100d lg11ud |g12ud curreg lagreg1 lagregZ lagreg3 lagreg4 lagregS lagregG lagreg7 IagregB lagregQ PHS 20 y79 y80 y81 y82 y83 y84 y85 y86 y87 y88 y89 y90 y91 y92 y93 y94 cns car ant giu der res 119 90.83492 132.15497 0.76562 0.81439 Estimate 43.76404 1.57795 0.53202 1.50987 0.31569 1.19953 4.58277 0.09813 1.28424 0.97389 0.74747 0.71074 4.04324 1.55021 0.16474 0.07352 0.10489 0.16355 0.16750 0.02514 0.1 1095 0.17781 0.27403 0.08939 1 .62427 0.51507 4.071 16 4.27103 4.68294 0.62751 0.56966 0.26287 0.60325 0.73376 0.69773 -3.87933 4.21215 0.87520 4.10268 4.39225 4.84088 1.61674 1.15476 1.46372 2.55263 5.68986 4.95038 Poisson Std Err 10.45397 0.94665 1.33878 1.28563 1.30123 1.26407 1.28677 1.32936 1.29043 1.24789 1.12923 1.10366 1.09982 1.09583 0.18095 0.18351 0.18545 0.19317 0.18694 0.17597 0.15429 0.14520 0.14199 0.13812 1.26758 0.54195 0.78245 1.01509 1.30848 1.57752 1.77853 1.98411 2.18467 2.35278 2.47836 2.58864 2.68026 2.73665 2.83268 2.90156 2.97728 0.73175 0.70749 0.93173 1.60732 5.03860 3.81527 Poisson t-stat 4.31663 1.66688 4.89129 1.17442 0.24261 0.94894 4.23003 0.07382 0.99520 0.78043 0.66193 0.64399 0.94855 1.41464 0.91043 0.40063 0.56559 0.84663 0.89601 0.14285 0.71909 1.22456 4.92993 0.64718 1.28139 0.95041 4.36898 4.25214 4.28618 4.66560 4.44483 4.14050 4.64933 4.58696 4.49201 4.49860 4.57154 4.41604 4.44834 4.51376 4.62594 2.20940 1.63219 1.57098 1.58813 1.12925 1.29752 Robust Std Err 9.59022 0.41637 1.04546 0.73787 0.43556 0.46871 0.66929 1.13043 0.95171 0.37582 0.26630 0.47087 0.93974 0.59516 0.12884 0.17903 0.05555 0.09181 0.15196 0.14106 0.12345 0.09513 0.05462 0.04589 1.10867 0.35705 0.78359 0.83450 1.20372 1.38543 1.58557 1.88067 1.92882 2.15520 2.26595 2.45982 2.40985 2.45417 2.63021 2.67413 2.65328 0.53313 0.52061 0.76209 1.42799 4.61781 3.41802 Robust t-stat 4.43522 3.78975 0.42193 2.04624 0.72478 2.55923 0.36483 0.08681 1.34940 0.59138 2.80684 4.50942 4 .1 1014 2.60470 4.27869 0.41065 1.88805 1.78137 4.10226 0.17820 0.89876 1.86903 0.01660 4.94787 1.46506 4.44258 4.36698 4.52310 4 .3981 1 4.89654 4.62065 4.20323 4 .8681 1 4.73244 4.63187 4.57708 4.74788 4.57903 4.55983 4.64250 4.82449 3.03256 2.21807 1.92068 1.78756 1.23215 1.44832 166 Table 8.23 - Industry Lag 12. PHS Lag 15 (20% Depreciation) Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 90.77965 Sum of Sqr Resid 129.45617 R-Squared 0.77041 Sigma Squared 0.83427 Parameter Estimate one -7.66510 curird 1 . 16316 Ig1 ird 0.30456 lg2ird 1 .65123 lg3ird 0.08750 Ig4ird 1 .10484 lgSird 4 .79763 lg6ird 0.26959 lg7ird 1 .05945 lgBird 4 .07895 IgQird 0.67974 lg10ird 0.76571 Ig11ird 4.14118 Ig12ird 1 .77062 curreg 0. 17405 lagreg1 0.09670 lagreg2 0.05416 lagreg3 0.14933 lagreg4 0.20952 lagregS 0.06475 lagreg6 0.13691 lagreg7 0.16851 IagregB 0.31134 lagregQ 0. 12370 PHS 1 5 1 . 101 39 y79 0.32533 y80 0.61573 y81 0.52963 y82 0.60626 y83 4 .29640 y84 4 .02413 y85 0.42380 y86 4 .50866 y87 4 .42197 y88 4 . 19998 y89 4 .25721 y90 4.49125 y91 4 . 16282 y92 4 .29402 y93 4 .53096 y94 4 .95970 cns 1 .40570 car 1 . 14077 ant 1 .07145 giu 1 .51 181 der 3.03698 res 2.69447 Poisson Std Err 6.51472 0.96364 1.32653 1.29571 1.29468 1.25946 1.29561 1.31831 1.28988 1.26014 1.13528 1.11751 1.11253 1.13134 0.18194 0.18270 0.17965 0.19160 0.18587 0.17406 0.15066 0.14369 0.13947 0.13722 0.86322 0.48045 0.55579 0.55562 0.6031 1 0.70539 0.74096 0.72283 0.75776 0.78097 0.77411 0.79856 0.84576 0.90244 0.95587 1.00952 1.09580 0.58600 0.69871 0.65101 1.00301 3.12230 2.16229 4.17658 1 .20704 4 .73729 1 .27438 0.06759 0.87724 4 .38748 0.20450 0.82136 0.85622 0.59874 0.68520 4 .02575 1 .56507 0. 95664 0.52929 0.30146 0.77939 4 . 12723 0.37199 0. 90879 1 . 17272 0.23225 0.90142 1 .27591 0.67713 4 . 10785 0.95322 4 .00522 4 .83786 4 .38216 0.58630 4 .99094 4 .82078 4 .55013 4 .57434 4 .76321 4 .28853 4 .35377 4 .51653 4 .78837 2.39879 1 .63268 1 .64583 1 .50727 0.97268 1 .24612 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err 2.99916 0.58308 1.13612 0.74172 0.56708 0.45417 0.77618 1.23290 1.09344 0.43470 0.21666 0.50602 0.94680 0.66458 0.12176 0.17593 0.04370 0.10010 0.15361 0.12758 0.12244 0.08463 0.04088 0.03853 0.31034 0.22526 0.44269 0.36247 0.29431 0.44626 0.25928 0.4871 1 0.36217 0.40314 0.48879 0.46031 0.36261 0.38904 0.49040 0.60785 0.54417 0.20817 0.27045 0.15308 0.44198 1.33928 0.98101 Robust t-stat 0.55575 1.99485 0.02844 2.22624 0.15431 2.43265 0.31601 0.21866 0.96891 0.48208 3.13739 4.51321 4.20530 2.66428 4.42941 0.54965 1.23940 1.49191 4.36392 0.50754 4 .1 1824 1.991 16 -7.61647 -3.21074 3.54897 4.44425 4.39087 4 .461 15 0.05993 0.90505 0.94993 0.87002 4.16563 0.52725 0.45498 0.73125 -4.1 1256 0.98892 0.63872 0.51866 0.60127 6.75256 4.21799 6.99921 3.42053 2.26763 2.74662 167 Table 8.24 - Industry Lag 12. PHS Lag 18 (20% Depreciation) Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R.Squared Sigma Squared Parameter one curird lg1kd ngkd |gSkd Ig4nd lgsnd Ig6kd lg7nd IgBWd ngHd lg100d Ig11kd ig12fld curreg kxfieg1 kmuegZ Iagnxx3 kxneg4 kxyegS kxyeQG kuyeg7 kuyegB kuyegQ PHS16 y79 y80 y81 y82 y83 y84 y85 y86 y87 y88 y89 y90 y91 y92 y93 y94 cns car ant gut der res 119 91.08372 128.52412 0.77206 0.82435 Esfinune 0.08930 1.09929 0.33204 1.76961 0.07605 1.07752 4.80922 0.29854 1.09344 4.14877 0.69514 0.77660 4.15351 1.77702 0.16578 0.08889 0.05722 0.15692 0.20293 0.06323 0.13553 0.16125 0.31435 0.12270 1.37294 0.40218 0.79744 0.73626 0.84352 4.59451 4.39203 0.83787 4.91980 4.81219 4.61076 4.63367 4.88489 4.49600 4.72055 4.95287 0.36722 1.56137 1.28880 1.23895 1.70916 3.92801 3.39270 Poisson Std Err 6.70342 0.96950 1.32881 1.30657 1.29903 1.26154 1.29631 1.31945 1.28257 1.25705 1.13141 1.11417 1.10605 1.12502 0.18205 0.18283 0.17965 0.19205 0.18596 0.17468 0.15057 0.14381 0.13944 0.13702 0.9121 1 0.48922 0.59821 0.61071 0.66990 0.79324 0.86234 0.86868 0.89641 0.90513 0.90668 0.91303 0.96201 0.98955 1.07996 1.12795 1.20347 0.60955 0.70314 0.67080 1.02849 3.26695 2.31218 4.35592 1.13387 4.75499 1.35440 0.05854 0.85413 4.39567 0.22626 0.85254 0.91386 0.61441 0.69702 4.04292 1.57955 0.91059 0.48619 0.31849 0.81710 4.09130 0.36195 0.90013 1.12126 0.25432 0.89548 1.50524 0.82209 4.33305 4.20558 4.25917 0.01013 4.61426 0.96453 0.14164 0.00213 4.77654 4.78928 4.95932 4.51179 4.59315 4.73135 4.96699 2.56150 1.83292 1.84696 1.66181 1.20235 1.46732 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err 3.431 12 0.60204 1 .1 1916 0.75876 0.56662 0.43718 0.761 10 1.22760 1.08139 0.41 174 0.22272 0.52927 0.93888 0.66813 0.121 16 0.17521 0.04133 0.09795 0.15479 0.13018 0.1 1790 0.08516 0.04124 0.03979 0.38340 0.23086 0.48240 0.40991 0.35909 0.48509 0.36141 0.58895 0.48009 0.49033 0.57435 0.55359 0.42673 0.46592 0.59990 0.71750 0.65680 0.23603 0.29315 0.19186 0.48443 1 .60876 1 . 18285 Robust t—stat 0.64908 1.82593 0.08375 2.33224 0.13421 2.46468 0.37712 0.24319 1.01 1 14 0.79004 3.12114 4.46731 4.22861 2.65969 4.36823 0.50731 1.38424 1.60200 4.31105 0.48566 4.14953 1.89338 -7.62265 0.08363 3.58095 4 .7421 1 4.65306 4.79615 0.34903 0.28705 0.85170 4.42264 0.99882 0.69585 0.80447 0.95104 4.41703 0.21084 0.86805 0.72177 0.60418 6.61527 4.39645 6.45740 3.52818 2.44165 2.86824 168 Table 8.25 - Industry Lag 12. PHS Lag 17 (20% Depreciation) Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 91.90392 Sum of Sqr Resid 124.13129 R-Squared 0.77985 Sigma Squared 0.80258 Parameter Estimate Poisson Std Err Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err Robust t-stat one 42.78483 7.24538 4.76455 4.24606 0.01099 curird 0.96013 0.98105 0.97867 0.63322 1.51626 Ig1ird 0.28754 1.33096 4.71871 1.06388 0.15018 lg2ird 1.89096 1.31650 1.43636 0.78242 2.41682 lg3ird 0.07156 1.30038 0.05503 0.53374 0.13407 Ig4ird 1.08089 1.26525 0.85429 0.43029 2.51198 lgSird 4.86766 1.29568 4.44145 0.77130 0.42146 lgGird 0.36269 1 .32467 0.27380 1 .20668 0.30057 lg7ird 1.03579 1 .27897 0.80987 1 .05234 0.98427 IgBird 4.18560 1.24864 0.94951 0.40862 0.90149 ngird 0.71562 1.1 1989 0.63902 0.20951 3.41576 lg10ird 0.75435 1.10850 0.68051 0.53923 4.39893 Ig11ird 4.16381 1.09549 4.06237 0.92000 4.26501 tg12ird 1.79026 1.11445 1.60641 0.68271 2.62228 curreg 0.13176 0.18382 0.71677 0.11615 4.13436 lagreg1 0.07075 0.18315 0.38629 0.17139 0.41279 lagregZ 0.06153 0.17915 0.34346 0.03714 1.65694 lagreg3 0.16330 0.19232 0.84910 0.09702 1.68311 lagreg4 0.18432 0.18726 0.98429 0.15487 4.19011 IagregS 0.05493 0.17558 0.31282 0.13207 0.41588 IagregG 0.12214 0.15128 0.80741 0.11612 4.05182 lagreg7 0.15371 0.14379 1.06903 0.08195 1.87582 lagrege 0.32673 0.14015 0.33134 0.04331 -7.54406 tagregQ 0.12300 0.13680 0.89914 0.03841 0.20276 PHS 17 2.00149 1.00721 1.98716 0.53468 3.74336 y79 0.60876 0.51 138 4.19044 0.24757 0.45897 y80 4.18364 0.66744 4.77341 0.52601 0.25020 y81 4.25991 0.72861 4.72920 0.51196 0.46097 y82 4.40440 0.79347 4.76994 0.47061 0.98421 y83 0.25796 0.94087 0.39986 0.58173 0.88145 y84 0.20115 1.06118 0.07425 0.53809 4.09071 y85 4.73153 1.10290 4.56998 0.77318 0.23947 y86 0.87240 1.14982 0.49814 0.71892 0.99542 y87 0.75623 1.15076 0.39513 0.67530 4.081 48 y88 0.54898 1.15049 0.21555 0.74521 0.42046 y89 0.60238 1.16677 0.23043 0.73585 0.53657 y90 0.80988 1.18906 0. 3631 1 0.60674 4.63108 y91 0.44597 1.22156 0.00234 0.67203 0.63967 y92 0.61800 1.27922 0.04657 0.78871 0.31935 y93 0.99301 1.37836 0.17144 0.94657 0.16195 y94 0.39641 1.44107 0.35686 0.91526 0.71087 cns 1.91179 0.65194 2.93244 0.31669 6.03681 car 1 .63372 0.72370 2.25747 0.36283 4.50270 ant 1.63656 0.71923 2.27544 0.28464 5.74951 giu 2.23407 1.10257 2.02624 0.58123 3.84371 der 6.09558 3.59599 1.69510 2.09562 2.90872 res 5.03791 2.59854 1.93875 1.56035 3.22871 169 Table 8.28 - industry Lap 12, PHS Lag 18 (20% Depreciation) Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 91.83871 Sum of Sqr Resid 124.00166 R-Squared 0.78008 Sigma Squared 0.79865 Parameter Estimate Poisson Std Err Poisson t—stat Robust Std Err Robust t-stat one 44.62530 8.10106 4.80535 5.79942 0.52186 curird 1.13502 0.96638 1.17450 0.56330 2.01493 Ig1ird 0.51553 1.33699 4.88149 1.01323 0.48270 ngird 1.93091 1.31799 1.46505 0.80842 2.38851 Ig3ird 0.17005 1.30169 0.13064 0.48612 0.34982 lg4ird 1.09162 1.26174 0.86517 0.44889 2.43179 lgSird 4.79441 1.28978 4.39125 0.75738 0.36924 IgGird 0.18083 1.31780 0.13722 1.15162 0.15702 lg7ird 1.17339 1.27969 0.91694 1.01940 1.15107 lgBird 4.19120 1.24737 0.95497 0.40668 0.92912 IgQird 0.7681 1 1.1 1705 0.68762 0.25104 3.05965 lg10ird 0.75517 1.09752 0.68806 0.56342 4.34034 lg11ird 4.10178 1.09088 4.00999 0.93444 4.17908 Ig121rd 1 .66074 1.09925 1.51080 0.64976 2.55592 curreg 0.11238 0.18507 0.60725 0.11228 4.00088 lagreg1 0.03954 0.18554 0.21309 0.17641 0.22411 lagreg2 0.08283 0.17992 0.46035 0.03679 2.25119 lagregB 0.16480 0.19210 0.85785 0.09422 1.74910 lagreg4 0.16725 0.18758 0.89163 0.15134 4.10511 lagregS 0.03440 0.17622 0.19520 0.13245 0.25971 lagreg6 0.11651 0.15190 0.76704 0.11651 4.00005 lagreg7 0.15791 0.14421 1.09495 0.08773 1.79994 IagregB 0.32277 0.14021 0.30208 0.04387 -7.35771 lagregQ 0.12757 0.13718 0.92994 0.03076 4.14735 PHS 18 2.22707 1.14431 1.94621 0.71642 3.10862 y79 0.70661 0.53832 4.31261 0.28920 0.44331 y80 4.39918 0.75000 4.86558 0.61730 0.26662 y81 4 .58584 0.87796 4 .80629 0.60937 0.60241 y82 4.87098 1.00911 4.85409 0.69140 0.70606 y83 0.73041 1.15768 0.35853 0.75513 0.61584 y84 0.73209 1.31488 0.07783 0.82002 0.33174 y85 0.39363 1.42476 4.68003 1.06172 0.25449 y86 0.61297 1.50355 0.40295 1.03457 0.49224 y87 0. 57332 1.53642 0.32575 1.02471 0.48716 y88 0.37570 1.54018 0.19176 1.06784 0.16124 y89 0.43330 1.55694 0.20516 1.11111 0.08997 y90 0.68232 1.58845 0.31819 0.99422 0.70374 y91 0.25393 1.58877 0.04808 1.04544 0.11250 y92 0.46216 1.65799 0.08816 1.19605 0.89467 y93 0.73489 1.71048 0.18354 1.28682 0.90242 y94 4.26318 1.81928 0.34333 1.28698 0.31254 cns 2.00817 0.70413 2.85198 0.35502 5.65648 car 1.67831 0.75413 2.22549 0.40711 4.12245 ant 1.78954 0.80604 2.22017 0.42833 4.17791 giu 2.54355 1.22134 2.08258 0.78458 3.24193 der 7.03314 4.09172 1.71887 2.80765 2.50499 res 5.80281 3.00824 1.92897 2.03939 2.84536 170 Table 8.27 - Industry Lag 12, PHS Lag 19 (20% Depreciation) Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R-Squared Sigma Squared Parameter one curird Ig1ird ngird IgBird Ig4ird igSird IgGird lg7ird igBird ngird lg10ird lg11kd |g120d cu rreg lagreg1 lagreg2 lagreg3 lagreg4 lagregS lagreg6 lagreg7 IagregB lagregQ PHS 19 y79 y80 y81 y82 y83 y84 y85 y86 y87 y88 y89 y90 y91 y92 y93 y94 cns car ant giu der res 119 91.54301 126.70392 0.77529 0.8033 Estimate 4 5.32770 1.29249 0.48482 1.66535 0.31886 1.12336 4.67524 0.04258 1.19066 4.08068 0.73515 0.68537 4.09708 1.60645 0.11564 0.03112 0.11702 0.16980 0.16329 0.02262 0.09516 0.16101 0.29975 0.11542 2.17987 0.72509 4.44291 4.71068 0.08911 0.04384 0.99686 0.71884 4.03762 4.08695 0.96782 4.03989 4.28990 0.89840 4.04472 4.35183 4.75623 1.93510 1.55081 1.77606 2.71681 7.17141 5.94521 Poisson Std Err 9.01573 0.95450 1.33821 1.29580 1.30260 1 .26350 1.28327 1.31934 1.28196 1.24669 1.1 1650 1.09722 1.08628 1.09505 0.18490 0.18695 0.18360 0.19305 0.18706 0.17652 0.15478 0.14466 0.14039 0.13683 1.23593 0.56046 0.81283 1.00843 1.20625 1.41373 1.56382 1.72459 1.86124 1.94249 1.98891 2.01229 2.04154 2.05585 2.09231 2.16267 2.20560 0.72543 0.75153 0.87266 1.36791 4.53728 3.37069 4.70011 1.35411 4.85682 1.28519 0.24479 0.88909 4.30544 0.03227 0.92878 0.86684 0.65844 0.62464 4.00995 1.46701 0.62544 0.16644 0.63735 0.87956 0.87297 0.12813 0.61480 1.11301 0.13516 0.84354 1.76376 4.29374 4.77517 4.69638 4.73191 0.15306 4.91638 4.57651 0.16931 0.10397 4.99497 0.00761 0.10130 4.89625 4.93314 0.01225 0.15644 2.66754 2.06355 2.03522 1.98610 1.58055 1.76380 Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err 7.87571 0.49233 1.00124 0.74968 0.43051 0.42246 0.67945 1.11622 1.01 186 0.38435 0.24228 0.51 135 0.88839 0.61107 0.1 1339 0.18220 0.05047 0.09106 0.15595 0.13454 0.12299 0.09375 0.04910 0.03253 0.97196 0.36251 0.75053 0.79864 0.99253 1.161 10 1.23434 1.53096 1.50641 1.61697 1.69710 1.74760 1.66271 1.69430 1.83363 1.94164 1.89042 0.46442 0.50453 0.61548 1.12220 3.88467 2.82734 Robust t-stat 4.94620 2.62526 0.48174 2.22140 0.74068 2.65907 0.46558 0.03815 1.17671 0.81 174 3.03430 4.34031 4.23491 2.62890 4.01989 0.17077 2.31862 1.86466 4.04707 0.1681 1 0.77373 1.71747 -6. 10520 0.54841 2.24276 0.00021 4.92253 0.14198 0.10483 0.62152 0.42791 4.77591 0.68029 0.52754 0.33800 0.31 168 0.58007 0.30089 0.20586 0.24131 0.51596 4.16674 3.07379 2.88564 2.42095 1.84608 2.10276 171 Table 8.28 - Industry Lag 12. PHS Lag 20 (20% Depreciation) Num of Obs Log Likelihood Sum of Sqr Resid R-Squared Sigma Squared Parameter one curird lg1ird igZird Ig3ird lg4ird IgSird lgGird lg7ird lgBird ngird lg100d lg11Wd ig12ud curreg lagreg1 iagregZ lagreg3 lagreg4 IagregS IagregG lagreg7 lagreg8 iagregQ PHS 20 y79 y80 y81 y82 y83 y84 y85 y86 y87 y88 y89 y90 y91 y92 y93 y94 cns car ant giu der res 119 90.80243 131.17883 0.76735 0.81526 Estimate 12.30732 1.48427 0.51883 1.57639 0.27568 1.19411 4.61488 0.04915 1.26486 4.01220 0.75695 0.73141 4.04548 1.55875 0.15795 0.06368 0.10829 0.16834 0.17418 0.03152 0.11298 0.17580 0.28904 0.10000 1.56730 0.53959 4.11464 4.30447 4.67868 0.59117 0.50752 0.14928 0.45511 0.53853 0.45178 0.58104 0.84200 0.44891 0.62304 0.86059 4.29798 1.59139 1.15699 1.38120 2.37813 5.33482 4.60217 Poisson Std Err 9.48287 0.94267 1.33877 1.28928 1.30078 1.26379 1.28550 1.32402 1.28837 1.24956 1.12868 1.10265 1.09740 1.09468 0.18156 0.18519 0.18641 0.19394 0.18630 0.17564 0.15448 0.14537 0.14089 0.13740 1.23102 0.55346 0.81256 1.04424 1.31254 1.55869 1.74040 1.90730 2.08253 2.21690 2.30403 2.37482 2.41374 2.42800 2.48543 2.51744 2.58530 0.71469 0.71017 0.87898 1.48991 4.77761 3.56235 4.29785 1.57454 4.88145 1.22270 0.21193 0.94486 4.25623 0.03712 0.98175 0.81005 0.67065 0.66332 0.95269 1.42393 0.86996 0.34387 0.58095 0.86799 0.93497 0.17944 0.73132 1.20930 0.05145 0.72780 1.27317 0.97495 4.37176 4.24920 4.27895 4.66240 4.44078 4.12687 4.65909 4.59616 4.49815 4.50792 4.59172 4.42047 4.45771 4.53354 4.66247 2.22668 1.62919 1.57136 1.59615 1.11663 1.29189 Poisson t—stat Robust Std Err 9.21307 0.43518 1.03669 0.75135 0.441 11 0.46437 0.66763 1.12763 0.97071 0.37596 0.26654 0.50087 0.94735 0.59135 0.12406 0.18402 0.05838 0.08820 0.15282 0.13427 0.12381 0.09589 0.05016 0.03994 1.14751 0.39935 0.84802 0.93747 1.28448 1.50247 1.64563 1.94772 1.97013 2.18073 2.28224 2.40847 2.33788 2.34123 2.48611 2.52810 2.52146 0.57342 0.57437 0.74137 1.42265 4.73159 3.48257 Robust t-stat 4.33585 3.41067 0.42968 2.09807 0.62497 2.57146 0.41881 0.04358 1.30303 0.69234 2.83992 4.46027 4.10359 2.63594 4.27317 0.34607 1.85499 1 .90867 4.13978 0.23472 0.91249 1.83340 0.76214 0.50344 1.36583 4 .351 17 4.31441 4.39148 4.30690 4.72461 4 .52374 4.10348 4.75375 4.62264 4.51245 4.48685 4.64337 4.47311 4.45731 4.52707 4.70456 2.77524 2.01436 1.86305 1.67162 1.12749 1.32149 172 Table 8.29 - CES Estimation, Industry Stock, PHS Lap 17 Num of Obs 119 Log Likelihood 85.60683 Sum of Sqr Resid 157.39969 R-Squared 0.72085 Sigma Squared 0.86354 Parameter Estimate Poisson Std Err Poisson t-stat Robust Std Err Robust t-stat one 42.57139 7.34271 4.71209 3.43194 0.66306 pmastk 0.37727 0.60367 0.62495 0.08840 4.26772 curreg 0.00160 0.16680 0.00959 0.11096 0.01441 lagregt 0.07798 0.17226 0.45271 0.19918 0.39151 lagregZ 0.01255 0.17057 0.07356 0.06404 0.19591 IagregS 0.10685 0.17085 0.62539 0.08246 1.29580 lagreg4 0.10738 0.17491 0.61392 0.11282 0.95177 IagregS 0.04804 0.16374 0.29341 0.08669 0.55420 IagregS 0.17629 0.13971 4 .26185 0.08480 0.07888 lagreg7 0.00773 0.13460 0.05746 0.06765 0.11432 lagrega 0.21319 0.13068 4.63131 0.07941 0.68475 IagregQ 0.09284 0.12469 0.74457 0.06190 4.49975 Sub. Term "In IB" 0.39956 0.38627 4.03441 0.18243 0.19025 PHS 17 2.17691 1.07206 2.03059 0.51710 4.20987 y79 0.80972 0.47188 4.71595 0.19330 4.1 8897 y80 4.29032 0.62151 0.07609 0.41322 0.12261 y81 4 .18566 0.72201 4.64216 0.30088 0.94057 y82 4.44470 0.84000 4.71987 0.33353 4.33158 y83 0.23738 0.97755 0.28875 0.44679 -5.00762 y84 0.28497 1.07709 0.12143 0.37905 0.02818 y85 4 .98746 1.14403 4.73724 0.50197 0.95934 y86 0.67459 1.20855 0.21305 0.50347 0.31229 y87 0.75211 1.25028 0.20120 0.49959 0.50873 y88 0.88482 1 .27791 0.25745 0.54848 0.25969 y89 0.83874 1.31414 0.16016 0.63553 4.46674 y90 0.07269 1.36072 0.25814 0.55788 0.50781 y91 0.76602 1.40481 4.96897 0.58017 4.76759 y92 0.01832 1.44518 0.08854 0.67811 4.45111 y93 0.38523 1.54156 0.19597 0.82557 4.10047 y94 0.68344 1.58429 0.32499 0.68446 0.38155 cns 1 .63057 0.68381 2.38452 0.19438 8.38861 car 1.18282 0.71853 1.64617 0.19423 6.08970 ant 1.39464 0.78660 1.77300 0.27105 5.14535 giu 2.29671 1.07898 2.12859 0.49002 4.68699 der 5.94926 3.71685 1 .60062 1.62456 3.66208 res 4.72136 2.65658 1.77724 1.11399 4.23824 ‘3- 173 Table 8.30 - Indirect Eflect, PHS Concurrent Lag Total SS: 62.081 R-squared: 0.979 Residual SS: 1.324 F(29,75): 118.708 Durbin-Watson: 1 .169 Degrees of Freedom: 75 Rbar-squared: 0.97 Std error of Est: 0.133 Probability of F: 0 Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment Standard Standardized Cor with Variable Estimate Error t-value Prob > It) Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 7.9002 2.2464 3.5169 0.0010 PHS BASIC Concurrent 0.1744 0.1760 0.9909 0.3250 0.2890 0.8707 LOGSALE 0.1488 0.1251 1.1896 0.2380 0.1256 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 4504) 0.7132 0.2266 3.1475 0.0020 0.9299 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 4 .0936 0.2361 4.6326 0.0000 4 .3408 0.5758 CURREG 0.0248 0.0292 0.8492 0.3980 0.0201 0.1778 LAGt REG 0.0167 0.0263 0.6351 0.5270 0.0145 0.2097 LAGZREG 0.0031 0.0270 0.1159 0.9080 0.0029 0.2836 LAG3REG 0.0223 0.0274 0.8155 0.4170 0.0205 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0158 0.0288 0.5483 0.5850 0.0140 0.3334 CNS 0.9411 0.2959 3.1807 0.0020 0.4283 0.2878 CAR 0.3710 0.1902 4 .9501 0.0550 0.1688 0.3282 ANT 0.5022 0.2464 2.0376 0.0450 0.2285 0.3460 GIU 0.0935 0.2181 0.4287 0.6690 0.0426 0.2333 DER 4 .3017 0.6507 0.0005 0.0490 0.5924 0.6446 RES 4 .0855 0.3764 0.8837 0.0050 0.4940 0.3747 YR72 0.0825 0.0757 1.0906 0.2790 0.0268 0.1031 YR73 0.1165 0.0815 1.4292 0.1570 0.0378 0.0815 YR74 0.1942 0.0848 2.2904 0.0250 0.0630 0.0456 YR75 0.1853 0.0901 2.0564 0.0430 0.0601 0.0396 YR76 0.0258 0.0943 0.2732 0.7850 0.0084 0.0588 YR77 0.0847 0.0977 0.8662 0.3890 0.0275 0.0363 YR78 0.0963 0.1010 0.9530 0.3440 0.0312 0.0254 YR79 0.0693 0.1053 0.6587 0.5120 0.0225 0.0110 YR80 0.1540 0.1087 1.4169 0.1610 0.0500 0.0211 YR81 0.1697 0.1113 1.5247 0.1320 0.0551 0.0363 YR82 0.2622 0.1166 2.2484 0.0270 0.0850 0.0772 YR83 0.3291 0.1215 2.7095 0.0080 0.1068 0.1135 YR84 0.2998 0.1345 2.2286 0.0290 0.0973 0.1318 YR85 0.3604 0.1465 2.4610 0.0160 0.1169 0.1550 Table 8.31 - Indirect Effect. PHS Lac 1 Total SS: R-squared: Residual SS: F(29.75): Durbin-Watson: Degrees of Freedom: Rbar-squared: Std error of Est: Probability of F : Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment 62.081 0.979 1.317 119.297 1.174 75 0.971 0.133 0 174 Standard Standardized Cor with Variable _ Estimate Error t-value Prob > [t] Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 7.7872 2.2426 3.4723 0.0010 PHS BASIC LAG 1 0.1853 0.1595 1.1623 0.2490 0.3070 0.8727 LOGSALE 0.1630 0.1267 1.2864 0.2020 0.1375 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 4504) 0.6746 0.2349 2.8716 0.0050 0.8796 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 4 .0734 0.2343 4.5809 0.0000 4 .3160 0.5758 CURREG 0.0237 0.0291 0.8158 0.4170 0.0192 0.1778 LAGt REG 0.0155 0.0263 0.5915 0.5560 0.0135 0.2097 LAG2REG 0.0021 0.0270 0.0772 0.9390 0.0019 0.2836 LAG3REG 0.0211 0.0274 0.7695 0.4440 0.0194 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0143 0.0289 0.4968 0.6210 0.0127 0.3334 CNS 0.9181 0.2832 3.2420 0.0020 0.4178 0.2878 CAR 0.3492 0.1888 4 .8497 0.0680 0.1589 0.3282 ANT 0.4650 0.2497 1.8626 0.0660 0.2116 0.3460 GIU 0.1024 0.1951 0.5249 0.6010 0.0466 0.2333 DER 4 .3085 0.6166 0.1219 0.0370 0.5955 0.6446 RES 4 .0673 0.3562 0.9962 0.0040 0.4857 0.3747 YR72 0.0893 0.0761 1.1729 0.2450 0.0290 0.1031 YR73 0.1218 0.0818 1.4894 0.1410 0.0395 0.0815 YR74 0.2071 0.0860 2.4075 0.0190 0.0672 0.0456 YR75 0.1969 0.0911 2.1612 0.0340 0.0639 0.0396 YR76 0.0478 0.0952 0.5019 0.6170 0.0155 0.0588 YR77 0.0982 0.0968 1.0140 0.3140 0.0319 0.0363 YR78 0.1099 0.0990 1.1109 0.2700 0.0357 0.0254 YR79 0.0853 0.1001 0.8526 0.3970 0.0277 0.0110 YR80 0.1662 0.1032 1.6104 0.1120 0.0539 0.0211 YR81 0.1794 0.1046 1.7155 0.0900 0.0582 0.0363 YR82 0.2693 0.1098 2.4532 0.0160 0.0874 0.0772 YR83 0.3367 0.1131 2.9775 0.0040 0.1092 0.1135 YR84 0.3061 0.1239 2.4709 0.0160 0.0993 0.1318 YR85 0.3617 0.1355 2.6699 0.0090 0.1173 0.1550 Table 8.32 - Indirect Effect. PHS Lag 2 Total SS: R-squared: Residual SS: F(29,75): Durbin-Watson: Degrees of Freedom: Rbar-squared: Std error of Est: Probability of F: Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment 62.081 0.979 1.299 121.027 1.181 75 0.971 0.132 0 175 Standard Standardized Cor with Variable Estimate Error t—value Prob > It] Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 7.5153 2.2318 3.3674 0.0010 PHS BASIC LAG 2 0.2317 0.1485 1.5604 0.1230 0.3832 0.8742 LOGSALE 0.1862 0.1277 1.4575 0.1490 0.1571 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 4504) 0.6050 0.2409 2.5114 0.0140 0.7889 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 4 .0487 0.2331 4.4995 0.0000 4 .2857 0.5758 CURREG 0.0232 0.0285 0.8119 0.4190 0.0188 0.1778 LAG1 REG 0.0146 0.0260 0.5639 0.5740 0.0127 0.2097 LAG2REG 0.0003 0.0268 0.0113 0.9910 0.0003 0.2836 LAG3REG 0.0189 0.0273 0.6916 0.4910 0.0173 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0127 0.0286 0.4431 0.6590 0.0113 0.3334 CNS 0.9074 0.2752 3.2970 0.0010 0.4130 0.2878 CAR 0.2929 0.1890 4 .5500 0.1250 0.1333 0.3282 ANT 0.4133 0.2528 1.6347 0.1060 0.1881 0.3460 GIU 0.0851 0.1796 0.4740 0.6370 0.0387 0.2333 DER 4 .2426 0.5952 0.0878 0.0400 0.5655 0.6446 RES 0.9818 0.3466 0.8326 0.0060 0.4468 0.3747 YR72 0.0942 0.0756 1.2459 0.2170 0.0306 0.1031 YR73 0.1324 0.0819 1.6178 0.1100 0.0430 0.0815 YR74 0.2175 0.0859 2.5310 0.0130 0.0706 0.0456 YR75 0.2151 0.0922 2.3342 0.0220 0.0698 0.0396 YR76 0.0633 0.0957 0.6616 0.5100 0.0205 0.0588 YR77 0.1227 0.0976 1.2562 0.2130 0.0398 0.0363 YR78 0.1209 0.0982 1.2310 0.2220 0.0392 0.0254 YR79 0.0945 0.0982 0.9621 0.3390 0.0306 0.0110 YR80 0.1759 0.1002 1.7564 0.0830 0.0571 0.0211 YR81 0.1830 0.1006 1.8196 0.0730 0.0594 0.0363 YR82 0.2667 0.1057 2.5237 0.0140 0.0865 0.0772 YR83 0.3298 0.1090 3.0263 0.0030 0.1070 0.1135 YR84 0.2962 0.1179 2.5136 0.0140 0.0961 0.1318 YR85 0.3433 0.1287 2.6688 0.0090 0.1114 0.1550 Table 8.33 - Indiect Effect. PHS Lag 3 Total SS: 62.081 R-squared: 0.98 Residual SS: 1.265 F(29,75): 124.306 Durbin-Watson: 1.188 Degrees of Freedom: 75 Rbar—squared: 0.972 Std error of Est: 0.13 Probability of F: 0 176 Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment Standard Standardized Cor with Variable Estimate Error t-value Prob > It) Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 7.1554 2.2052 3.2448 0.0020 PHS BASIC LAG 3 0.2976 0.1405 2.1187 0.0370 0.4913 0.8762 LOGSALE 0.2168 0.1276 1.6982 0.0940 0.1829 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 45-64) 05118 0.2434 2.1026 0.0390 0.6674 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 4 .0150 0.2311 4.3920 0.0000 4 .2444 0.5758 CURREG 0.0233 0.0279 0.8338 0.4070 0.0189 0.1778 LAG1 REG 0.0159 0.0254 0.6263 0.5330 0.0138 0.2097 LAG2REG 0.0001 0.0263 0.0055 0.9960 0.0001 0.2836 LAG3REG 0.0162 0.0269 0.6004 0.5500 0.0149 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0106 0.0282 0.3747 0.7090 0.0094 0.3334 CNS 0.8976 0.2690 3.3368 0.0010 0.4085 0.2878 CAR 0.2133 0.1887 4.1308 0.2620 0.0971 0.3282 ANT 0.3461 0.2539 1.3631 0.1770 0.1575 0.3460 GIU 0.0586 0.1686 0.3474 0.7290 0.0267 0.2333 DER 4 .1405 0.5782 4 .9724 0.0520 0.5190 0.6446 RES 0.8507 0.3418 0.4891 0.0150 0.3872 0.3747 YR72 0.0894 0.0739 1.2097 0.2300 0.0290 0.1031 YR73 0.1283 0.0797 1.6094 0.1120 0.0416 0.0815 YR74 0.2219 0.0842 2.6344 0.0100 0.0720 0.0456 YR75 0.2180 0.0898 2.4266 0.0180 0.0707 0.0396 YR76 0.0751 0.0945 0.7946 0.4290 0.0244 0.0588 YR77 0.1290 0.0962 1.3412 0.1840 0.0418 0.0363 YR78 0.1358 0.0973 1.3949 0.1670 0.0440 0.0254 YR79 0.0912 0.0969 0.9415 0.3490 0.0296 0.0110 YR80 0.1709 0.0988 1.7307 0.0880 0.0554 0.021 1 YR81 0.1786 0.0984 1.8153 0.0730 0.0579 0.0363 YR82 0.2517 0.1039 2.4238 0.0180 0.0817 0.0772 YR83 0.3073 0.1076 2.8560 0.0060 0.0997 0.1135 YR84 0.2650 0.1167 2.2718 0.0260 0.0860 0.1318 YR85 0.3032 0.1269 2.3883 0.0190 0.0984 0.1550 Table 8.34 - Indirect Eflect. PHS Lag 4 Total SS: R-squared: Residual SS: F(29,75): Durbin-Watson: Degrees of Freedom: Rbar-squared: Std error of Est: Probability of F: Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment 62.081 0.98 1.24 126.942 1.22 75 0.972 0.129 0 177 Standard Standardized Cor with Variable Estimate Error t-value Prob > [t] Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 6.9067 2.1866 3.1587 0.0020 PHS BASIC LAG 4 0.3331 0.1344 2.4779 0.0150 0.5485 0.8783 LOGSALE 0.2327 0.1266 1.8385 0.0700 0.1964 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 4504) 0.4562 0.2427 1.8797 0.0640 0.5949 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 0.9797 0.2302 4.2561 0.0000 4 .2012 0.5758 CURREG 0.0236 0.0275 0.8552 0.3950 0.0191 0.1778 LAG1 REG 0.0189 0.0250 0.7558 0.4520 0.0164 0.2097 LAG2REG 0. 0031 0.0259 0.1201 0.9050 0.0029 0.2836 LAGBREG 0.0166 0.0265 0.6258 0.5330 0.0152 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0093 0.0279 0.3325 0.7400 0.0082 0.3334 CNS 0.8799 0.2651 3.3194 0.0010 0.4004 0.2878 CAR 0.1623 0.1881 0.8630 0.3910 0.0739 0.3282 ANT 0.3087 0.2526 1.2220 0.2260 0.1405 0.3460 GIU 0.0556 0.1609 0.3456 0.7310 0.0253 0.2333 DER 4 .0700 0.5700 4 .8772 0.0640 0.4870 0.6446 RES 0.7540 0.3426 0.2007 0.0310 0.3431 0.3747 YR72 0.0799 0.0729 1.0959 0.2770 0.0259 0.1031 YR73 0.1057 0.0782 1.3518 0.1810 0.0343 0.0815 YR74 0.1993 0.0819 2.4338 0.0170 0.0647 0.0456 YR75 0.2030 0.0875 2.3215 0.0230 0.0659 0.0396 YR76 0.0575 0.0918 0.6262 0.5330 0.0187 0.0588 YR77 0.1204 0.0944 1.2745 0.2060 0.0390 0.0363 YR78 0.1204 0.0959 1.2554 0.2130 0.0391 0.0254 YR79 0.0899 0.0959 0.9376 0.3510 0.0292 0.0110 YR80 0.1520 0.0986 1.5406 0.1280 0.0493 0.0211 YR81 0.1601 0.0984 1.6268 0.1080 0.0519 0.0363 YR82 0.2356 0.1035 2.2766 0.0260 0.0764 0.0772 YR83 0.2828 0.1082 2.6129 0.0110 0.0917 0.1135 YR84 0.2342 0.1179 1.9869 0.0510 0.0760 0.1318 YR85 0.2640 0.1291 2.0452 0.0440 0.0857 0.1550 Table 3.35 - Indirect Effect. PHS Lac 5 Total SS: R-squared: Residual SS: F(29,75): Durbin-Watson: Degrees of Freedom: Rbar-squared: Std error of Est: Probability of F: Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment 62.081 0.981 1.202 130.943 1.231 75 0.973 0.127 0 178 Standard Standardized Cor with Variable Estimate Error t-value Prob > It] Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 6.5958 2.1575 3.0572 0.0030 PHS BASIC LAG 5 0.3807 0.1295 2.9405 0.0040 0.6255 0.8805 LOGSALE 0.2442 0.1240 1 .9699 0.0530 0.2061 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 4504) 0.4094 0.2362 1.7335 0.0870 0.5338 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 0.9471 0.2277 4.1588 0.0000 4.1611 0.5758 CURREG 0.0218 0.0271 0.8036 0.4240 0.0177 0.1778 LAG1 REG 0.0211 0.0246 0.8571 0.3940 0.0183 0.2097 LAGZREG 0.0076 0.0254 0.2975 0.7670 0.0070 0.2836 LAGBREG 0.0199 0.0259 0.7677 0.4450 0.0183 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0090 0.0274 0.3294 0.7430 0.0080 0.3334 CNS 0.8759 0.2608 3.3587 0.0010 0.3986 0.2878 CAR 0.1062 0.1846 0.5752 0.5670 0.0483 0.3282 ANT 0.2906 0.2469 1.1769 0.2430 0.1322 0.3460 GIU 0.0395 0.1555 0.2537 0.8000 0.0180 0.2333 DER 0.9435 0.5651 4 .6698 0.0990 0.4294 0.6446 RES 0.6174 0.3456 4 .7866 0.0780 0.2810 0.3747 YR72 0.0636 0.0718 0.8855 0.3790 0.0206 0.1031 YR73 0.0746 0.0777 0.9598 0.3400 0.0242 0.0815 YR74 0.1535 0.0813 1.8878 0.0630 0.0498 0.0456 YR75 0.1571 0.0858 1.8305 0.0710 0.0510 0.0396 YR76 0.0206 0.0899 0.2290 0.8190 0.0067 0.0588 YR77 0.0774 0.0927 0.8344 0.4070 0.0251 0.0363 YR78 0.0862 0.0950 0.9075 0.3670 0.0280 0.0254 YR79 0.0484 0.0962 0.5026 0.6170 0.0157 0.0110 YR80 0.1257 0.0985 1.2765 0.2060 0.0408 0.0211 YR81 0.1138 0.1007 1.1303 0.2620 0.0369 0.0363 YR82 0.1894 0.1060 1.7864 0.0780 0.0614 0.0772 YR83 0.2384 0.1105 2.1575 0.0340 0.0773 0.1135 YR84 0.1799 0.1215 1.4812 0.1430 0.0584 0.1318 YR85 0.2000 0.1338 1.4946 0.1390 0.0649 0.1550 Table 8.38 - Indirect Effect. PHS Lag 6 Total SS: R-squared: Residual SS: F (29,75): Durbin-Watson: Degrees of Freedom: Rbar—squared: Std error of Est: Probability of F: Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment 62.081 0.981 1.175 134.056 1.238 75 0.974 0.125 0 179 Standard Standardized Cor with Variable Estimate Error t-value Prob > It) Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 6.3384 2.1399 2.9620 0.0040 PHS BASIC LAG 6 0.4204 0.1292 3.2552 0.0020 0.6896 0.8825 LOGSALE 0.2419 0.1213 1.9941 0.0500 0.2041 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 4504) 0.3954 0.2291 1.7261 0.0880 0.5156 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 0.9248 0.2257 4.0969 0.0000 4 .1339 0.5758 CURREG 0.0219 0.0268 0.8158 0.4170 0.0177 0.1778 LAG1 REG 0.0218 0.0244 0.8952 0.3740 0.0189 0.2097 LAGZREG 0.0115 0.0252 0.4561 0.6500 0.0106 0.2836 LAGBREG 0.0248 0.0255 0.9726 0.3340 0.0228 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0120 0.0270 0.4460 0.6570 0.0107 0.3334 CNS 0.8867 0.2579 3.4377 0.0010 0.4035 0.2878 CAR 0.0677 0.1826 0.3709 0.7120 0.0308 0.3282 ANT 0.3059 0.2407 1.2710 0.2080 0.1392 0.3460 GIU 0.0207 0.1535 0.1349 0.8930 0.0094 0.2333 DER 0.8009 0.5689 4 .4077 0.1630 0.3645 0.6446 RES 0.4799 0.3570 4 .3441 0.1830 0.2184 0.3747- YR72 0.0548 0.0712 0.7700 0.4440 0.0178 0.1031 YR73 0.0447 0.0783 0.5710 0.5700 0.0145 0.0815 YR74 0.1069 0.0833 1.2835 0.2030 0.0347 0.0456 YR75 0.0937 0.0884 1.0603 0.2920 0.0304 0.0396 YR76 0.0426 0.0916 0.4652 0.6430 0.0138 0.0588 YR77 0.0218 0.0942 0.2318 0.8170 0.0071 0.0363 YR78 0.0236 0.0976 0.2418 0.8100 0.0077 0.0254 YR79 0.0024 0.0988 0.0245 0.9810 0.0008 0.01 10 YR80 0.0674 0.1024 0.6588 0.5120 0.0219 0.0211 YR81 0.0741 0.1032 0.7182 0.4750 0.0240 0.0363 YR82 0.1282 0.1119 1.1454 0.2560 0.0416 0.0772 YR83 0.1781 0.1166 1.5276 0.1310 0.0578 0.1135 YR84 0.1244 0.1268 0.9809 0.3300 0.0403 0.1318 YR85 0.1351 0.1408 0.9591 0.3410 0.0438 0.1550 Table 8.37 - Indirect Effect, PHS Lag 7 Total SS: R-squared: Residual SS: F(29,75): Durbin-Watson: Degrees of Freedom: Rbar-squared: Std error of Est: Probability of F: Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment 62.081 0.981 1.169 134.714 1.245 75 0.974 0.125 0 180 Standard Standardized Cor with Variable Estimate Error t-value Prob > It] Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 6.0088 2.1641 2.7766 0.0070 PHS BASIC LAG 7 0.4562 0.1375 3.3179 0.0010 0.7478 0.8839 LOGSALE 0.2383 0.1205 1.9767 0.0520 0.2010 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 4504) 0.4001 0.2265 1.7664 0.0810 0.5218 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 0.9046 0.2263 0.9968 0.0000 4 .1090 0.5758 CURREG 0.0212 0.0267 0.7934 0.4300 0.0172 0.1778 LAGi REG 0.0233 0.0243 0.9604 0.3400 0.0203 0.2097 LAGZREG 0.0133 0.0251 0.5295 0.5980 0.0122 0.2836 LAG3REG 0.0286 0.0254 4 .1238 0.2650 0.0263 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0159 0.0268 0.5919 0.5560 0.0141 0.3334 CNS 0.8946 0.2575 3.4749 0.0010 0.4071 0.2878 CAR 0.0409 0.1866 0.2191 0.8270 0.0186 0.3282 ANT 0.3403 0.2373 1.4343 0.1560 0.1549 0.3460 GIU 0.0024 0.1552 0.0153 0.9880 0.0011 0.2333 DER 0.6324 0.5908 4 .0705 0.2880 0.2878 0.6446 RES 0.3363 0.3867 0.8698 0.3870 0.1531 0.3747 YR72 0.0483 0.0712 0.6791 0.4990 0.0157 0.1031 YR73 0.0275 0.0795 0.3455 0.7310 0.0089 0.0815 YR74 0.0657 0.0874 0.7520 0.4540 0.0213 0.0456 YR75 0.0360 0.0945 0.3815 0.7040 0.0117 0.0396 YR76 0.1163 0.0990 4 .1748 0.2440 0.0377 0.0588 YR77 0.0527 0.1017 0.5189 0.6050 0.0171 0.0363 YR78 0.0417 0.1045 0.3993 0.6910 0.0135 0.0254 YR79 0.0747 0.1076 0.6945 0.4900 0.0242 0.01 10 YR80 0.0083 0.1099 0.0756 0.9400 0.0027 0.021 1 YR81 0.0077 0.1127 0.0687 0.9450 0.0025 0.0363 YR82 0.0829 0.1188 0.6978 0.4870 0.0269 0.0772 YR83 0.1099 0.1284 0.8559 0.3950 0.0357 0.1135 YR84 0.0583 0.1389 0.4201 0.6760 0.0189 0.1318 YR85 0.0757 0.1525 0.4968 0.6210 0.0246 0.1550 Table 8.38 - Indirect Effect. PHS Lag 8 Total SS: R-squared: Residual SS: F(29,75): Durbin-Watson: Degrees of Freedom: Rbar-squared: Std error of Est: Probability of F: Dependent Variable: Log of Industry R&D Investment 62.081 0.981 1.195 131.757 1.246 75 0.973 0.126 0 181 Standard Standardized Cor with Variable Estimate Error t-value Prob > It) Estimate Dep Var CONSTANT 5.9795 2.2150 2.6996 0.0090 — PHS BASIC LAG 8 0.4620 0.1527 3.0259 0.0030 0.7581 0.8850 LOGSALE 0.2191 0.1209 1.8116 0.0740 0.1849 0.8624 INCTHRE (age 4504) 0.4484 0.2262 1.9823 0.0510 0.5846 0.6558 SEVTWO (age 1544) 0.9154 0.2290 0.9982 0.0000 4.1223 0.5758 CURREG 0.0228 0.0270 0.8439 0.4010 0.0185 0.1778 LAG1 REG 0.0234 0.0246 0.9533 0.3430 0.0204 0.2097 LAG2REG 0.0149 0.0255 0.5867 0.5590 0.0137 0.2836 LAG3REG 0.0300 0.0257 -1 .1658 0.2470 0.0276 0.2937 LAG4REG 0.0185 0.0271 0.6846 0.4960 0.0165 0.3334 CNS 0.9186 0.2612 3.5168 0.0010 0.4180 0.2878 CAR 0.0591 0.1932 0.3058 0.7610 0.0269 0.3282 ANT 0.3972 0.2371 1.6755 0.0980 0.1808 0.3460 GIU 0.0099 0.1624 0.0611 0.9510 0.0045 0.2333 DER 0.5486 0.6278 0.8738 0.3850 0.2497 0.6446 RES 0.2741 0.4298 0.6377 0.5260 0.1247 0.3747 YR72 0.0270 0.0732 0.3690 0.7130 0.0088 0.1031 YR73 0.0028 0.0839 0.0328 0.9740 0.0009 0.0815 YR74 0.0320 0.0952 0.3361 0.7380 0.0104 0.0456 YR75 0.0190 0.1071 0.1775 0.8600 0.0062 0.0396 YR76 0.1856 0.1145 4 .6210 0.1090 0.0602 0.0588 YR77 0.1385 0.1205 4 .1499 0.2540 0.0449 0.0363 YR78 0.1272 0.1237 4 .0277 0.3070 0.0413 0.0254 YR79 0.1488 0.1260 4 .1813 0.2410 0.0483 0.0110 YR80 0.0722 0.1301 0.5551 0.5800 0.0234 0.021 1 YR81 0.0569 0.1311 0.4338 0.6660 0.0185 0.0363 YR82 0.0121 0.1398 0.0868 0.9310 0.0039 0.0772 YR83 0.0641 0.1459 0.4393 0.6620 0.0208 0.1135 YR84 0.0073 0.1630 0.0448 0.9640 0.0024 0.1318 YR85 0.0176 0.1774 0.0992 0.9210 0.0057 0.1550 BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Acs, Zoltan J., David B. Audretsch, and Maryann P. Feldman. (1991) “Real Effect of Academic Research: Comment,” American Economic Review, March 1991, pp. 363067. Adams, James D. (1990) “Fundamental Stocks of Knowledge and Productivity Growth,“ Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, No. 4, 1990, pp. 673-702. Baily, Martin N. (1972) "Research and Development Costs and Returns: The US. Pharmaceutical Industry," Journal of Political Economy, January/February 1972, pp. 70-85. Bloom, Barry M. (1976) “Socially Optimal Results from Drug Research,” in Impact of Pgblic Policy on Drug Innovation and Pricing, Samuel A. Mitchell (editor), Washington, DC: The American University, 1976. Blundell, Richard, Rachel Griffith, and John Van Reenen. (1995) “Dynamic Count Data Models of Technological Innovation,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 105, March 1995, pp. 333-344. Cockbum, Iain and Rebecca Henderson. (1994) “Racing to Invest? Dynamics of Competition in Ethical Drug Discovery,” Journal of Economics 8 Management Strategy, Vol. 3, No. 3, Fall 1994, pp. 481 -519. Davidson, R. and J. MacKinnon. (1981) “Several Tests for Model Specification in the Presence of Alternative Hypotheses,” Econometrica, Vol. 49, 1981, pp. 781 -793. DiMasi, Joseph A., Ronald W. Hansen, Henry G. Grabowski, and Louis Lasagna. "Cost of innovation in the pharmaceutical industry," Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 10, 1991, pp. 107-142. Dranove, David, and David Meltzer. (1994) “Do important drugs reach the market sooner?” Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 25, No. 3, Autumn, 1994, pp. 402423. 182 183 Gambardella, Alfonzo. (1992) “Competitive advantages from in-house scientific research: The US pharmaceutical industry in the 1980s,” Research Policy, Vol. 21, 1992, pp. 391407. Gambardella, Alfonzo. (1995) Science and Innovation: The US pharmaceutical industm during the 19803, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1 995. Grabowski, Henry, and John Vernon. (1981) “The Determinants of Research and Development Expenditure in the Pharmaceutical Industry,” in Drugs and Health, Robert B. Helms (editor), Washington DC: The AEI Press, 1981. Grabowski, Henry, and John Vernon. (1994) “Innovation and Structural Change in Pharmaceuticals and Biotechnology,” Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 3, No. 2, 1994, pp. 435-449. Grabowski, Henry, and John Vernon. (1996) “Prospects for returns to Pharmaceutical R&D under Health Care Reform,” in Competitive Strategies in the Pharmaceutical Industry, Robert B. Helms (editor), Washington DC: The AEI Press, 1996. Grabowski, Henry 6., John M. Vernon, and Lacy Glenn Thomas. (1978) “Estimating the Effects of Regulation on Innovation: An lntemational Comparative Analysis of the Pharmaceutical Industry,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 21, No. 1, April 1978, pp. 133-163. Griliches, Zvi. (1979) “Issues in Assessing the Contribution of Research and Development to Productivity Growth,” Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 10, Spring 1979, pp. 92416. Griliches, Zvi. (1984) R&D. Paients and Productivity, (ed.) Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1984. Griliches, Zvi. (1986) “Productivity, R&D, and Basic Research at the Firm Level in the 1970s,” American Economic Review, March 1986, pp. 1141-154. Griliches, Zvi. (1991) "The Search for R&D Spillovers," NBER Working Paper, No. 3768, July 1991. Govemment-University-Industry Research Roundtable. (1989) Science and Technology in the Academic Enterprise: Status, Trends, and Issues, Washington DC: National Academy Press, October, 1989. 184 Hall, Bronwyn H., Clint Cummins, Elizabeth S. Laderman, and Joy Mundy. (1988) “The R&D Master File Documentation,” NBER Technical Working Paper Series, December 1988. Hall, Bronwyn H., Zvi Griliches, and Jerry Hausman. (1986) “Patents and R&D: Is there a Lag?” lntemational Economic Review, Vol. 27, No. 2, June 1986, pp. 265-283. Hausman, Jeny, Bronwyn H. Hall, and Zvi Griliches. (1984) “Econometric Models for Count Data with an Application to the Patents-R&D Relationship,” Econometrica, Vol. 52, No. 4, July 1984, pp. 909-938. Henderson, Rebecca. (1994) “The Evolution of Integrative Capability: Innovation in Cardiovascular Drug Discovery,” Industrial and Corporate Change, Vol. 3, No. 2, 1994, pp. 607-627. Henderson, Rebecca and Iain Cockbum. (1996) "Scale, Scope and Spillovers: The Determinants of Research Productivity in the Pharmaceutical Industry," Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 27, No. 1, Spring 1996, pp. 3209. Henderson, Rebecca and Iain Cockbum. (1997) “Public-Private Interaction and the Productivity of Pharmaceutical Research,” NBER Working Paper Series, No. 6018, April 1997. Jaffe, Adam B. (1989) "Real Effects of Academic Research," American Economic Review, December 1989, pp. 957-970. Jenson, Elizabeth J. (1987) “Research Expenditures and the Discovery of New Drugs,” The Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 36, No. 1, September 1987, pp. 83-95. Kmenta, Jan. (1967) “On Estimation of the CES Production Function,” International Economic Review, Vol. 8, No. 2, June 1967, pp. 180489. Link, Albert. (1981) “Basic Research and Productivity Increase in Manufacturing: Additional Evidence,” American Economic Review, Vol. 71, No. 5, December 1981, pp. 1111-1112. Mairesse, Jacques and Mohamed Sassenou. (1991) “R&D and Productivity: A Survey of Econometric Studies at the Firm Level,” NBER Working Paper Series, Working Paper No. 3666, March 1991. 185 Mansfield, Edwin, John Rapoport, Jerome Schnee, Samuel Wagner, and Michael Hamburger. (1971) Research and Innovation in the Modern Comoration, New York: WW. Norton 8 Company Inc., 1971. Mansfield, Edwin. (1980) “Basic Research and Productivity Increase in Manufacturing,” American Economic Review, December 1980, pp. 863- 873. Mansfield, Edwin. (1991) "Academic Research and Industrial Innovation,” Research Policy, Vol. 20, 1991, pp. 142. Mansfield, Edwin. ( 1995) "Academic Research Underlying Industrial Innovations: Sources, Characteristics, and F inancing,” Review of Economics and Statistics, March 1995, pp. 5505. Maxwell, Robert A., and Shohreh B. Eckhardt. (1990) Drug Discovegy: A Case Book and Analysis, Clifton, NJ: Humana Press, 1990. Gourieroux, C., A. Monfort, and A. Trognon. (1984) “Pseudo Maximum Likelihood Methods: Applications to Poisson Models,” Econometrica, Vol. 52, 1984, pp. 701-720. National Institutes of Health. (1989) NIH Data Book 1989, US. Department of Health and Human Services, 1989. National Science Foundation. Science and Technology Data Sock, Washington DC. NSF, 1985. National Science Foundation. National Patterns of R&D Resources: 1992, by J.E. Jankowski, Jr., NSF 92030 (Washington DC, 1992). Pakes, Ariel, and Zvi Griliches. (1980) "Patents and R&D at the Firm Level: A First Look," in R&D, Patents, and Productivity, Zvi Griliches (editor), Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1984. Peltzman, Sam. (1973) An Evaluation of Consumer Protection Legislation: The 1962 Drug Amendments,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81, No. 5, September/October 1 973, pp. 1 0494 091 . Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Association. "Annual Survey Report," PMA, Washington DC, various years. 186 Romer, Paul M. (1990) "Endogenous Technological Change," Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98, 871-8102. Romer, Paul M. (1994) “The Origins of Endogenous Growth,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 8, No.1, Winter 1994, pp. 1302. Scolnick, Edward M. (1990) "Basic Research and its Impact on Industrial R&D," Research Technology Management, Vol.33, November/December 1990, pp. 2206. Scherer, Fredric M., and William S. Comanor. (1996) “Commentary on Part Three,” in Competitive Strategies in the Pharmaceutical Industgy, Robert B. Helms (editor), Washington DC: The AEI Press, 1996. Thomas, Lacy Glen. (1990) “Regulation and firm size: FDA impacts on innovation,” Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 24, No. 4, Winter 1990, pp. 497-517. Trajtenberg, Manuel. (1990) “A Penny for your quotes: patent citations and the value of innovations,” Rand Journal of Economics, Vol. 21, No. 1, Spring 1990, pp. 172-185. Trajtenberg, Manuel, Rebecca Henderson, Adam Jaffe. (1992) “Ivory Tower Versus Corporate Lab: An Empirical Study of Basic Research and Appropriability,” NBER Working Paper Series, No. 4146, 1992. US. Department of Commerce, Current Industrial Reports: Pharmaceutical Preparations except Biologicals. Washington DC: US. Government, September, 1994. US. Congress, Office of Technology Assessment, Pharmaceutical R&D: Sosts, Risks and Rewards, OTA-H022 (Washington, DC: US. Government Printing Office, February, 1 993). Ward, Michael R., and David Dranove. (1995) “The Vertical Chain of Research and Development in the Pharmaceutical Industry," Economic Inquiry, Vol. 33, 1995, pp. 70-87. Wiggins, Steven. (1979) Regulation and Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industm, Unpublished MIT Ph.D. Dissertation, 1979. 187 Wiggins, Steven. (1981) “Product Quality Regulation and Drug Introductions,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 63, November 1981, pp. 615- 619 Wiggins, Steven. (1983) “The Impact of Regulation on Pharmaceutical Research Expenditures: A Dynamic Approach,” Economic Inquiry, Vol. 21, January 1983, pp. 115-128. Wiggins, Steven. (1987) “The Effect of US. Pharmaceutical Regulation on New Introductions," in Arne Rvngvmposipm on Pharmaceutical Economics, B. Lindgren (editor), Stockholm, Swedish Institute for Health Economics, 1987. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (1989) “A Computationally Simple Heteroscedasticity and Serial Correlation Robust Standard Error for the Linear Regression Model,” Economic Letters, Vol. 31, 1989, pp. 239-243. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (1991) “On the Application of robust, regression-based diagnostics to models of conditional means and conditional variances,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 47, 1991, pp. 5-46. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (1994) “Multiplicative Panel Data Models Without the Strict Exogeneity Assumption,” mimeo, Michigan State University, January 1994. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (1996) "Quasi-Likelihood Methods for Count Data," in Handbook of Applied Econometrics, M.H. Pesaran and Peter Schmidt (eds), Volume II, forthcoming.