' LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. DATE DUE MTE DUE DATE DUE 'E‘Bezerw me mus-914 ESSAYS ON ASYMMETRIES, UNCERTAINTY, AND INVESTMENT By Woojin Youn A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1998 ABSTRACT ESSAYS 0N ASYMMETRIES, UNCERTAINTY, AND INVESTMENT By Woojin Youn This dissertation is a study of the investment decisions of firms, when they are constrained by uncertainty and behavioral asymmetries. The options approach to investment encompasses all the models presented in each context. Asymmetries are shown to give rise to options that affect the firm's decision to invest under uncertainty. Chapter 1 describes a general conceptual framework of option analysis. After a brief introduction to the financial option theory, applications to physical investments are presented by working through a simple example. The basic techniques of valuing options on the investment are discussed. Chapter 2 is concerned with the effectiveness of tax policy under uncertainty and irreversible investment expenditures. The focus of analysis is to investigate how taxes, uncertainty, and sunk costs interact in effecting the firm’s cost of capital and investment. The cost-of—capital formula is derived, and is compared with its neoclassical version. We find that sunk costs and uncertainty may be more important determinants of investment than taxes. The simulated paths of investment show that the model is empirically relevant and valid. Chapter 3 examines how asymmetries in the tax system affect the firm’s investment decisions under uncertainty and irreversibility. The asymmetries in the tax system are modeled to include an incomplete loss offset and a stepwise tax credit. We interpret tax claims as complex options on the firm's uncertain revenue. We find in this model as well that uncertainty has a more powerful effect on investment than does taxes. The model identifies the option effect through which the lack of a loss offset discourages investment. We find that the conditions for tax neutrality need some modification under uncertainty and irreversibility. Chapter 4 deals with investment decisions in the presence of moral- hazard problems in financial markets. In the model, the financial markets are characterized by the bankruptcy option of firms, loan guarantees by the government, and asymmetric information that encourage moral hazard. A simple option framework shows how moral hazard leads to the overborrowing problem. The cost-of—capital calculations find that a moral- hazard-prone economy is likely to be contaminated by risky investments and the volatility of investment. We also argue that government intervention in loan markets may sometimes be justified in a specific context. Copyright by WOOJIN YOUN 1998 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The contributions of many people around me constitute an integral part of this dissertation. Without their support and encouragement, I would have hard time in completing my work. The greatest debt is, of course, due to Charles L. Ballard, chairman of my dissertation committee. From the selection of a topic to the final touches on the product, he has made consistent suggestions and comments, so that my work was always on the right track. I am grateful to John H. Goddeeris and Jack Meyer, the other committee members, who advised me on the various parts of the dissertation. Collaboration with them has been challenging and rewarding. I would also like to thank the faculty of the Economics Department at Michigan State University for providing me excellent education in economics. l have benefited from discussions and cooperation with my fellow graduate students. Among them, Soomyung Jang, Sanghyop Lee, Younghoon Sea, and Min Chang deserve special thanks. They were kind enough to share with me their insight and knowledge. I would like to thank my wife, Yuja, and my two daughters, Sooyeon ($00) and Jungyeon (Debbie), for having gone through with me many ups and downs of my graduate study. Our life in East Lansing would not have been happier without their support and patience. My deepest gratitude goes to my father who has made me what I am today by providing encouragement and financial support. I am grateful to the Korea Institute for Industrial V Economics and Trade (KIET) for granting me a leave of absence and financial support. Finally, I would like to dedicate this dissertation to the memory of my mother who had always given a blind love to me. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS CHAPTER 1 OPTIONS AND INVESTMENT: A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK 1.1. Analogy Between Financial Options and Real Investment Decisions 1.2. The Basic Concepts of Option Valuation 1.3. An Application to Real Investment Decisions 1.3.1. Non-Traded Output 1.3.2. Traded Output CHAPTER 2 UNCERTAINTY, IRREVERSIBILITY, AND TAX POLICY 2.1. Introduction 2.2. Mathematical Preliminaries 2.2.1. Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion 2.2.2. ltO’s Lemma 2.2.3. Application of ltd's Lemma 2.3. The Basic Model 2.4. Tax-Adjusted Cost of Capital 2.5. Simulation of Investment Behavior 2.6. Summary and Conclusions vii IX 12 12 17 23 25 .29 36 36 4O 4O 42 44 .45 55 69 77 CHAPTER 3 TAX ASYMMETRIES, IRREVERSIBILITY, AND THE OPTIMAL INVESTMENT RULE. 3.1. Introduction 3.2. A Two-Period Decision Model 3.3. Tax Asymmetries and Tax Claims: An Option Interpretation 3.4. The Model of Dynamic Investment Decisions 3.4.1. Reversibility and the Value of the Firm 3.4.2. Irreversibility and the Option to Invest 3.5. Summary and Conclusions CHAPTER 4 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION, RISKY INVESTMENTS, AND FINANCIAL MARKET FRAGILITY.. 4.1. Introduction 4.2. Moral Hazard Problems in the Financial Market 4.2.1. Asymmetries, Options, and Risky Investments .. 4.2.2. A Simple Illustration 4.3. Bankruptcy Option, Loan Guarantees, and the Optimal Investment Rule 4.3.1. The Overborrowing Problem 4.3.2. The Dynamic Model of Investment Decisions 4.4. Financial Market Fragility and Financial Crisis 4.5. Summary and Conclusions viii ..80 ...80 84 95 100 .100 114 120 .. 122 122 125 125 .128 .131 131 .139 153 157 ..160 LIST OF TABLES Table 2.1 - Effect of the Tax and Uncertainty on the Threshold Prices (Costless Reversibility: E=R=2) Table 2.2 - Effect of Taxes and Uncertainty on the Threshold Prices (Costly Reversibility: E=2, R= 1.9) Table 2.3 - Effect of Taxes and Irreversibility on the Threshold Prices (Certainty Case: a=0) Table 2.4 - Effect of Taxes and Irreversibility on the Threshold Prices (Uncertainty Case: a=0.2) Table 2.5 - Tax Equivalent of an Increase in Uncertainty (percent. R=1.9) Table 3.1 - Uncertainty, Tax Rate and Optimal Price for Investment (Reversibility Case) Table 3.2 - Uncertainty, Tax Rate and Optimal Price for Investment (Irreversibility Case) Table 4.1 - Borrowing (D) and Threshold Price for Investment (P') (Risk-Neutral Firms) Table 4.2 - Borrowing (D) and Threshold Price for Investment (P‘) (Risk-Averse Firms) 60 .62 .64 65 .67 114 117 .147 147 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 2.1 - Effect of the Tax and Uncertainty on the Threshold Prices (Costless Reversibility: E=R=2) 60 Figure 2.2 - Effect of Taxes and Uncertainty on the Threshold Prices (Costly Reversibility: E=2, R= 1.9) 62 Figure 2.3 - Effect of Taxes and Irreversibility on the Threshold Prices (Certainty Case: a'=0) 64 Figure 2.4 - Effect of Taxes and Irreversibility on the Threshold Prices (Uncertainty Case: a=O.2) 65 Figure 2.5 - A Sample Path of Output Price 70 Figure 2.6 - A Simulated Path of Investment (Costless Reversibility Case) 72 Figure 2.7 - A Simulated Path of Investment (Costly Reversibility Case) 73 Figure 2.8 - Simulated Paths of Investment (For Higher Parameter Values) 75 Figure 3.1 - The Tax Rate It). the First-Period Revenue (R1). and the Value of Waiting (W) 89 Figure 3.2 - Uncertainty (0'), the First-Period Revenue (R1). and the Value of Waiting (W) 90 Figure 3.3 - The Loss Offset, the First-Period Revenue (3,), and the Value of Waiting (W) 91 Figure 3.4 - Firm's Revenue and Tax Claim 97 Figure 3.5 - The Tax System, the Output Price, and the Value of the Firm (a'=0.2) 110 Figure 3.6 - The Tax System, the Output Price, and the Value of the Firm (a'=O.4) 1 11 Figure 4.1 - Asset Value (X) and the Value of the Firm (V) (When X is certain) 135 Figure 4. 2- Asset Value (X) and the Value of the Firm (V) (When X is uncertain). Figure 4.3 - Asset Value (X) and the Value of the Firm (V) Figure 4.4 - Output Price (P) and Value of the firm (V) Figure 4.5 - Uncertainty (0') and Cost-of-Capital Lines (P’) xi .136 .138 .143 .151 ‘1. Introduction The study of investment is one of the most controversial areas in modern economics. No single theory has been accepted as coherent and satisfactory. The lack of integration in theory, in turn, has led to contradicting empirical results. Still, the characteristics of investment are not well understood, making it difficult to predict investment to a reasonably precise level, and rendering the study of investment tricky and cumbersome. This offers a reason why investment studies have continued to provide challenging tasks for both theorists and empirical researchers. This dissertation is a collection of essays on investment. Each of them aims at laying a small brick on a huge pile of literature in the field. There are many perspectives from which investment analysis can be tackled. As the title of the dissertation implies, it purports to examine a firm's investment decision problem in a situation, where the firm's capital decisions are constrained by some types of asymmetries, such as irreversible investment, and its operating environment is uncertain. Thus, the asymmetries and uncertainty that firms face in their investment decisions are essential elements of models to be proposed in each context. It would be a logical first step to place the relevant literature into a historical perspeCtive. The overview given below is not intended to be exhaustive, so the specific literature is relegated to each chapter, where appropriate. Over the last two decades. economic modeling that builds on ‘1 2 microeconomic foundations has pursued actively in almost every field of economics. We need to pay attention to two important achievements that have had a tremendous effect on economic analysis: the rational expectations hypothesis, and the role of rigidities and asymmetries in the economy. Needless to say, the rational expectations hypothesis has become an important working assumption for every economist. The role of rigidities and asymmetries in the economic behavior has also provided a good economic base on which to explain numerous economic phenomena. Injecting these two ideas into the standard frictionless and static expectations-based classical model has generated important dynamic results in many-economic applications. Its early success can be found in explaining the effectiveness of monetary policy induced by a nominal wage rigidity (e.g., Fisher (1977)). or in accounting for exchange rate dynamics associated with sticky prices in the goods sector (e.g., Dornbusch (1976)). In investment theory, attempts of this sort actually began in the early 19603. The origin of modern investment theory is the standard neoclassical theory represented by Jorgenson (1963). which assumes competitive conditions, and ignores uncertainty and rigidities. Subsequent theories attempted to extend the standard model by investigating other aspects of investment such as taxes (e.g., Hall and Jorgenson (1967)). Such models are considered elegant in their theoretical structure, but miss an important aspect of reality: they imply instantaneous and costless adjustments of investment in response to changing economic conditions, whereas the actual investment behavior is rather gradual. In the standard neoclassical model, 3 the firm’s forward-looking behavior has no role to play, and thus the expectations are assumed to be static. Eisner and Stortz (1963) is an initial attempt to introduce adjustment costs caused by the rigidity in capital expansion in order to develop dynamic and gradual adjustments of investment. Other important early contributions include Lucas (1967), Gould (1968), and Treadway (1969). The other strand of contributions endeavored to integrate the neoclassical theory with Tobin’s q-theory of investment. Hayashi (1982), for example, constructed a rigorous rational expectations model of investment to derive the optimal rate of investment as a function of q. Abel (1982) and Summers (1981) extended this line of work by highlighting the role of expectations in tax policy analysis. Increased uncertainty about economic conditions during the 19703 and 19803 urged capital theorists to turn their attention to modeling uncertainty. Hartman (1972) and Abel (1983b) extended earlier investment models to a stochastic setting, augmented by adjustment costs. They argued that high volatility in the output price tends to raise investment, because the firm's future profitability increases as uncertainty grows. In their models, a firm changes its labor-capital ratio in response to price fluctuations, which causes the marginal revenue product of capital to be convex in the output price. By Jensen's inequality, the firm's profit is increasing in price uncertainty. Abel (1983b) also shows that the optimal investment rule, which equates the marginal value of installed capital, or the marginal q, with the marginal adjustment cost, can be generalized into a case of uncertainty. L A, 4 Another type of rigidity recognized among economists is that firms are not able to reverse their investments costlessly. Arrow (1968) first showed in a deterministic context that, when investment is irreversible, firms invest under two alternating regimes—positive and zero investment. Research efforts to combine irreversibility in investment with the firm’s uncertainty are more recent. Theoretical developments along this line are much attributed to the advent of the theory of option pricing in financial economics. The early applications of option theory were limited to the financing aspects of the firm. Yet its applications have gradually expanded to capital budgeting and the investment process of the firm. Specifically, financial economists have increasingly recognized that investment projects abound with the option components in planning, project timing, expansion, contraction, etc. (See, for example, Trigeorgis (1996).). Economic application of the option theory to the investment process was pioneered by McDonald and Siegel (1986), using the option valuation technique developed by Black and Scholes (1973). They show that, if an investment is irreversible, there is an opportunity cost to investing today under uncertainty. This finding implies that uncertainty in the output price lowers investment, contradicting the pro-investment result mentioned before. There have since been burgeoning studies on investment that extend the option-based approach by allowing for more complexities. These developments are well documented in two separate surveys of Pindyck (1991) and Dixit (1992). Their co-authored book, Dixit and Pindyck (1994), also provides a systematic treatment of the new paradigm in investment theory. The research programs to explore new theoretical possibilities are "s 5 still underway ( See, for example, Abel and Eberly (1994, 1996), and Abel, et al. (1996).). The new view of investment has seriously altered the conventional wisdom on investment. The conventional approach to investment employs a basic principle that, if the net present value (NPV) of the project is greater than zero, firms should undertake it. This simple NPV rule, however, is based on an unrealistic premise that investment decisions are costlessly reversed or, if not, they are once-and-for-all opportunities. In reality, we can seldom observe an investment that meets this strict requirement. Investments usually incur expenditures that are at least partially irrecoverable, and thus are sunk. Firms can delay their investment decision, in an attempt to capture a better timing to maximize the expected profit of the project, as uncertainty resolves over time. When the investment is not completely irreversible, firms can also abandon the project. Thus, they have the flexibility of delaying and abandoning the investment, or, equivalently, have the option to invest and to abandon. These options have value, when the profitability of the project is uncertain. Once the firm invests, it loses the option to invest, while gaining the option to abandon. The value of options, therefore, must be added to, and subtracted from, the standard net present value. The option values are . adjustment costs of a different sort, that should be distinguished from those used in the traditional sense. As we will see, the implication for the optimal rule of investment is that firms do not invest until prices rise substantially, and do not disinvest until prices fall considerably. Dixit (1997) succinctly expressed these ideas as follows: 6 “Adjustment costs bring dynamics to a firm's factor demands. When these costs are linear—proportional to the amount of adjustment—or lump sum, the dynamics takes the form of intermittent action. No adjustment is made unless its marginal value is sufficiently high; therefore there is a range of inaction in the firm's decision rule. Uncertainty enlarges this range, because of the possibility that future developments may render the adjustment unnecessary; this can be expressed as the option value of the status quo." (p.1) The basic message of the option view of investment is clear: investment decision that is made 3 on the basis of the naive NPV rule is not necessarily an optimal, because it ignores options embedded in almost every investment project. Economists have increasingly taken the view seriously that committing resources to an investment involves options that have substantial values. The new approach to investment proves useful in resolving some empirical puzzles. In actual business decisions, it is not uncommon to require that a project should yield the expect rate of return much higher than the usual cost of capital. Summers (1987), for example, reports that firms are using the threshold rates of return with an average of 17 percent, although he calculated a nominal cost of capital taken from a survey at a time when expectations of inflation may have been fairly high. McCauley and Zimmer (1989) estimate the cost of capital for equipment and machinery in the U.S. at 9.1 to 13.5 percent for the period 1977-1988. The literature on irreversibility investment demonstrates that the value of the option to invest is substantial, so that the required rate of return could far exceed the level that the standard theory suggests. For instance. simulations performed in McDonald and Siegel (1986) show that projects should be implemented, only if their present value is twice as much as the investment costs. The neoclassical investment theory has also failed to ‘u 7 provide good empirical relationships to explain observed behaviors of aggregate investment. Aggregate econometric models do not fit the actual investment data well. Also, Tobin's q, or the cost of capital measures usually do not have strong explanatory power in explaining investment behavior. The recent alternative models move in the direction of offering a convincing interpretation of the empirical evidence by employing an option framework of analysis (e.g., Bertola and Caballero (1994)). Theories of irreversible investment emphasize the importance of sunk costs in the acquisition and disposition of capital. It is argued that even small sunk costs significantly affect the firm’s decision to invest, even when uncertainty is moderate. In the traditional investment theory, uncertainty can be accommodated by adding a risk premium to the discount rates, if it is associated with systematic (non-diversifiable) risk. Risk-averse firms then discount the project’s cash flows heavily, and behave in a cautious manner, when they make investment decisions. Craine (1989), and Bernheim and Shoven (1989) are attempts to employ a risk-premium approach. In the option-based theory, the role of uncertainty is far more fundamental, regardless of whether it is systematic. Risk-neutral as well as risk-averse firms can be severely influenced by the options associated with any type of uncertainty. This is why uncertainty, combined with irreversibility, takes a central position in the new theory, apart from other key determinants of investment. The preceding discussion is confined to the firm's option to invest resulting from irreversible investment. Yet firms abound with options, so long as they are able to get better information and/or more resilience. When 8 they are constrained by imperfect information, and systemic rigidities and asymmetries, firms react by gathering more information and enhancing flexibility. Information and resilience are given exogenously, or can be created by firms themselves. Many types of R&D investments are well suited for the latter case. They reveal useful information for firms to decide whether to undertake the follow-on investments that commercialize technologies therein. This implies that immediate investing in R&D, rather than waiting, may bring more valuable options to firms. We can think of many other contexts for firms to come up with growth options that increase firm value; see Kester (1984) for more discussion. Again, the option theory provides a good analytical tool to assess the correct value of the options involved. This dissertation studies how the firms’ investment decisions are made under uncertainty, when the firms are constrained by certain types of asymmetries. We assume that uncertainty is characterized by a specific stochastic process in the output price. However, asymmetries are different across models. In the model of Chapter 2, we assume a typical asymmetry that the investment is partially irreversible. In the model of Chapter 3, we employ an additional asymmetry in the tax function. More specifically, the tax system is characterized by the lack of loss offset, and a ceiling on the investment tax credit. In the model of Chapter 4, asymmetries are present in the firm's operating decisions: the firm can temporarily go bankrupt, and receive a'loan guarantee from the government, if the profits turn out to be unfavorable. The consistent theme throughout the models is the option 9 approach to investment. Against this general background, we present a brief description of each chapter contained. Chapter 1, ”Options and Investment: A Conceptual Framework," sets the scene for the rest of chapters by providing basic concepts and ideas about the options approach to investment. After a brief introduction to the financial option theory, we proceed with an application of the theory to physical investment, by working through a simple example. We present a method of valuing the options embedded in the investment, and show the equivalence of two solution techniques, namely, dynamic programming and option valuation methods. I Chapter 2, “Uncertainty, Irreversibility, and Tax Policy," is intended to answer the following fundamental question: does tax policy matter in stimulating investment? The effect of taxes on investment is one of the most controversial area in economics. To address this problem under uncertainty and irreversibility, we build a small model of a discrete investment with the parameterization of taxes, uncertainty and irreversibility. The model allows for flexibility in the firm's sunk costs of investment in order to show how investment is affected by the degree of irreversibility. The cost-of-capital formula derived from the model contains the three main parameters above, as well as others. The option interpretation of this formula is given in the context of the neoclassical investment theory. We also perform a sensitivity test to compare the effects of each parameter on the cost of capital to answer the question asked above. Finally, we simulate the behavior of investment, and assess 10 the response of investment to each parameter. Simulations will show that the model is empirically plausible. Chapter 3, ”Tax Asymmetries, Irreversibility, and the Optimal Investment Rule," examines how asymmetries in the tax system affect the firm's investment decisions under uncertainty and irreversibility. The model incorporates two representative tax asymmetries: an incomplete loss offset, and a stepwise tax credit. We interpret tax claims as options the tax authorities have on the firm’s uncertain revenue. Options are shown to vary, depending on which range of the revenue the firm is placed in. The option interpretation of the model proves intuitively very useful, and has a direct bearing on the neoclassical theory. From the solution and simulations of the model, we contend that uncertainty has a more powerful effect on investment than taxes, which is consistent with Chapter 2. We point out that the lack of a loss offset discourages investment, through the option effect stemming from uncertainty, irreversibility, and tax asymmetries combined. This conclusion contrasts with that of other models that emphasize the market risk-sharing role of taxes (e.g., Gordon (1985)). We reexamine the condition for neutrality of the tax system under uncertainty and irreversibility. and suggest a qualification for its application. Chapter 4, ”Asymmetric Information, Risky Investments, and Financial Market Fragility," deals with the effects of a moral-hazard problem on investment in financial markets. We employ the same analytical framework as in the previous chapters, since the model is characterized by asymmetries and uncertainty. The chapter starts with a discussion of asymmetric information and moral hazard in financial markets. We show, in a simple 11 option framework, how moral hazard leads to the overborrowing problem. Using again our dynamic model, we examine the investment decisions of firms, when they have the bankruptcy option and bank loans with repayment guarantees by the government. We show that a moral-hazard-prone economy is likely to be contaminated by risky investments and investment volatility. The role of asymmetric information and the risk attitudes of firms are scrutinized. We also argue that government intervention in loan markets may sometimes be justified in a specific context. Chapter 1 Options and Investment: A Conceptual Framework 1.1. Analogy Between Financial Options and Real Investment Decisions In the financial market, an option gives its owner the right—not the obligation—to buy or sell assets at a predetermined (exercise) price. A call option gives the right to buy, while a put option gives the right to sell. When the owner of an option buys or sells stock, it is called exercising the option. We can also distinguish options by the timing of exercising. An American option can be exercised at any time prior to expiry, whereas a European option can only be exercised at expiry. When an investment is characterized by irreversibility, the investment opportunity is equivalent to a financial call option.1 If the firm’s planning horizon is infinite, a commitment to an investment is like exercising an American call option with no expiry. A firm must decide whether to invest now or later in exchange for an irreversible expenditure. To make a term-by- term analogy, the investment opportunity available in the future is a financial option, the project to be undertaken is an associated financial asset, and the investment expenditure is the exercise price of the option. Once the call ' By an irreversible investment, we mean that the investment expenditure is sunk once spent. Irreversibility stems from various reasons, such as the firm- or industry-specific nature of capital, and the lemons problem in the sales market of capital. For simplicity, we assume complete irreversibility here. We will see below how incomplete irreversibility alters the options of the firm. 12 13 option is bought, the buyer cannot resell it to the seller. Likewise, once a firm proceeds with the investment, it cannot reverse its decision. An investment opportunity—or the option to invest—has value for the same reason as a financial option does. The option gives the holder a flexibility to optimize the timing of exercise. Let us take a stock option as an example. The price of the stock fluctuates, and is uncertain. When the holders of an option buy stock today by exercising the option, they will lose the opportunity to wait until tomorrow or a later date. This opportunity has value; if the stock price turns out to be higher than the exercise price, they can make a profit by buying stock. If the stock price turns out to be lower than the exercise price, they can avoid a loss by holding the option. By the same reasoning, the option to invest has value. The profitability of a project is uncertain, so firms can benefit from choosing to wait, and holding the option to invest. The option to invest is valuable since firms can capture upside gains, while eliminating downside losses; if the project turns out to be profitable, they will make a profit by investing. Otherwise, they will avoid a loss by withholding the investment. When waiting is costless, the investment will never be made because it always pays to wait. But waiting is not a free lunch; firms should give away cash flows from the investment that might be available over the period of waiting. If the cost of waiting is large enough to offset its benefit, the firm will initiate the investment. This is the basic thrust of the options approach to irreversible investment. A firm with a flexible system has a lot of options on various aspects of investment. As discussed above, the option to invest, which is a call option, is valuable, when the investment is irreversible. This option disappears, 14 when the investment is made. When the investment is reversible, the firm gains another option that has value, namely, the option to abandon the project. The option to abandon is a put option available after the investment is undertaken, because it is exercised by selling the capital. When the irreversibility is less than perfect, the value of the firm alters by investing immediately; it will decrease by losing the option to invest, and will increase by gaining the option to abandon. The higher degree of irreversibility increases the value of the lost option to invest, while decreasing the value of the option to abandon that is gained. If the irreversibility is more severe, therefore, the firm is less willing to invest immediately, because the value to be lost would be greater than the value to be gained by investing. The firm is also constrained by costly expandability as well as costly reversibility. Costly expandability arises because the firm may in the future buy capital at a price higher than the current level. In this case, waiting has an additional cost, since the investment expenditure is expected to increase. Waiting, or holding the option to invest, will reduce the firm value, increasing the incentive to invest today. Many options on investment are also associated with operating flexibility. A good example is the option to shut down the production operation temporarily. The firm will continue the operation, if the production line makes a positive profit; otherwise, it will cease production temporarily, and wait until the operation turns profitable. This operating option is another source of firm value. In effect, modern firms have made great strides in increasingly employing the flexible manufacturing system (FMS) of various sorts, substantially enhancing their 15 capital values. Usually, many types of options discussed so far intermingle in any investment, and affect the value of the firm? In the neoclassical investment theory, firms have few options associated with investment. This is because underlying the theory is the perfectly competitive and frictionless Arrow-Debreu world. The neoclassical investment theorists took this approach, because it provides a rationale for abstracting from complications caused by financial considerations of the firm.3 However, this simplified assumption results in two flaws that seem to be critical in real-world analysis: static expectations and the lack of options to the firm. In the neoclassical world, where investment is always reversible without any cost, the firm's expectations about the prospect for its profits are not important; the firm can adjust instantaneously and costlessly to its optimal path of capital stock, whenever expectations turn out to be incorrect, so that its capital stock deviates from the optimal level. Also costless reversibility and expandability in investment provide no role for options to play in determining the level of investment. The new view of investment, on the other hand, will attach a great importance both to expectations and options, since it rests totally on different assumptions. 2 The fact that the value of the options stems from flexibility implies that the option model has a wide range of economic and non-economic applications. The applications in economics range from wage bargaining to currency fluctuations. In finance, managerial operating flexibilities in capital budgeting are dubbed real options, as distinguished from financial options. See Dixit and Pindyck (1994), Chap. 1, for more discussion. 3 The neoclassical theory builds on the Modigliani-Miller (MM) theorem proposed in Modigliani and Miller (1958). The MM theorem argues that real economic decisions are independent of a firm's financial structure. In Chapter 4, we will see that the theorem fails to hold in the presence of asymmetries and options in financial markets. 16 Here is a simple illustration of how options work, even under a world of certainty. Consider a firm which plans an investment with the following net present value (NPV) of entire project evaluated at each future point in time: Year 0 1 2 3 4 5 Net Present Value -50 -20 30 37 21 18 (in thousands of dollars) Assume now that the firm has perfect information about the NPV to be earned. Let us first discuss the reversibility case. The firm need not delay investment so long as the NPV is positive, which implies that it may invest in Year 2. In Year 3, the firm can retrieve costlessly its investment in Year 2, and reinvest. Hence investing in Year 2 and Year 3 does not make any difference. This is not the case, if reversibility is costly. It is not optimal for the firm to invest in Year 2, since reversing the investment in Year 3 is costly. So the firm will wait and invest in Year 3. Irreversibility makes a difference even if there is no uncertainty. It is, therefore, optimal for the firm to pin down the best timing of investment along the time horizon. This implies that a positive net present value (NPV) does not mean that the project should be undertaken, nor does a negative NPV mean that it should be abandoned immediately. The optimal point to invest is Year 3. Waiting, therefore, has value equal to the difference between the two NPVs at Year 3 and Year 0: 17 $87,000= $37,000-(-$50,000). This value comes from the firm’s flexibility of delaying investment in response to irreversibility. 1.2. The Basic Concepts of Option Valuation The valuation of an option is based on the arbitrage principle in financial economics.4 Its basic principle—widely known as contingent claims analysis (CCAl—is associated with constructing a risk-hedging portfolio. To show how to do this in the European option case. let S be the current price of the underlying asset (a stock or a project under consideration). T be the time to expiry, and X be the given exercise price, respectively. The call and the put options have the same exercise price and expiration date. Intuitively, the option value is affected by the expected value. of S, which, in turn, depends on the current price of S, and the time T. Thus, we can denote the value of a call option by a functional relationship, 6/8, T; X), and the value of a put option by PIS, T; X). Consider first the value of the call at expiry, T=0. If S>X, the option will be exercised with a payoff equal to S- X; otherwise the option will expire worthless. This can be written as 0/8, 0; X)=Max[S-X, 0]. (1) By the same reasoning, the value of the put at expiry can be expressed as PIS, 0; X)=Max[X-S, 0]. (2) ‘ The valuation of options had been an intriguing but elusive question to financial economists for many years, before Fisher Black and Myron Scholes made a major breakthrough in their 1973 Journal of Political Economy paper. The option pricing model has since become an integral part of every finance textbook. See Brealey and Myers (1991), Chaps. 20 and 21, and Copeland, at al. (1991), Chap. 15, for a good introductory discussion. Wilmott, et al. (1995) offers a more rigorous treatment. 18 Consider now a portfolio consisting of holding long one stock and one put option, and holding short one call option. Then the value of the portfolio is given by F=S+P-C (3) The payoff for this portfolio at expiry is S +Max[X—S, 0]-Max[S-X, 0], (4) which can be written as S + lX-Sl-O =X if 896 (5’) S+0-(S-Xl=X if S>X (5") The payoff is always X, regardless of the value of the stock at expiry. Notice that the portfolio's risk has been eliminated by hedging. Since this payoff is given at expiry lT=0/. the next step is to value the portfolio prior to expiry (T: t, t>0). Assuming that the time is continuous, the portfolio should be worth Xe'", where r is the riskless interest rate, because the return from the riskless portfolio must equal the return from borrowing money that gives a sure amount of $X at expiry. If not, an arbitrage opportunity exists by a proper combination of buying and selling options and stocks, and borrowing or lending. The no-arbitrage condition stipulates a fundamental relationship between the asset values at time T=t, S+P-C=Xe'". (6) 19 This relationship is called the put-call parity, and serves as the basis of option valuation.5 As we have discussed, undertaking a (completely) irreversible investment is analogous to exercising an American call option. Assuming that waiting is costless. we can value the call option at time T=t as C = S-Xe’", (7) since complete irreversibility rules out the put option.“ The value of the call option equals that of a portfolio consisting of buying one unit of the stock, and at the same time borrowing money equal to the present value of the exercise price. We have so far discussed the option valuation in a world of perfect certainty, where investors have perfect information about the future prices of assets, and the return to all assets must be equal in equilibrium. In a world of uncertainty, the extended version of expression (7), widely known as the Black-Scholes formula, is used for option valuation. The formula contains the probability terms associated with the value of the underlying asset at expiry. We do not attempt to get into the Black-Scholes model because it is beyond our purpose: see Wilmott (1995) for a treatment.’ 5 This relationship is valid only for European options, since the values of American options may be different from those of European options due to early exercise. 6 When an American call option is for a dividend-paying stock, waiting incurs the cost of giving away the receipt of dividend payments. Accordingly, we are discussing how to value an American call option without dividends. American and European call options have the same value, if they are associated with non-dividend-paying stocks. Valuing an American option with dividends is a little tricky, because the cost of waiting should be considered. 7 The derivation of the Black-Scholes formula is cumbersome, involving the solution of a partial differential equation. It is used to value European call (put) options, and American call options with no dividends. 20 Instead. we will work through a two-period example to get an intuitive understanding of the idea. As a first step, let us denote the current stock price by S, and the value of a call option by C. S is assumed to go either up to S, with probability 0, or down to S, with probability (I-q) over the next period. The movement of S and C can be depicted as q/ S”; C” = M8XISU-X, 0] S 1'q 84; Cd=MaX[$d-X, 0]. The Black-Scholes formula is based on the principle that we can hedge the risk in a portfolio by taking opposite positions in the underlying stock and the call option since they are perfectly correlated. This is equivalent to saying that the call value is replicated by a hypothetical portfolio consisting (of buying N shares of the stock, and borrowing $8 worth of money at the risk-free interest rate. This is called a replicating strategy. Since the portfolio would exactly replicate the payoffs of the call option in any state of nature, their current values are also equal, such that C=NS-B. (8) In the following period, this relationship is expressed as C,,=NS,,-{1+rIB, (9) and 21 Cd=NSd-(7+r)8. (10) Solving these two equations for N and 8 gives N=£¢LL§1, (11) Su -8d and B=____Ns,—c,. (12) 1+r N is the amount of the stock required to replicate one option, and is called the option delta or hedge ratio. Substituting equations (11) and (12) back into equation (8) gives a useful formula to value the call option in terms of S, 8,, 8,,r, and X, C: pc, +rr-p1c,’ where p=11+rIS-Sd. (13) 1+r Su—Sd This formula has a remarkable feature. The probability q and the investors' attitudes toward risk are irrelevant to the formula. In equilibrium in the asset market, these factor alters the call value indirectly through their effect on S, S,,, 8,), and r. The attitudes toward risk do not matter, because every investor will take advantage of riskless arbitrage opportunities.‘3 To see this intuitively, we can rearrange equation (8) as NS-C=B. (14) a In some circumstances, where the underlying asset is not financial assets traded in the market, for example, risk preference affects the value of an option. We can accommodate this situation using an appropriate framework (e.g., capital asset pricing model (CAPM)). See Trigeorgis (1994), Chap. 3, for a more discussion. 22 which implies that a portfolio consisting of buying N shares of stock and selling short one call option replicates in the next period a sure amount of money equal to $(1 +r)B. If the equality does not hold, arbitrageurs intervene, and profit opportunities will be arbitraged away. This suggests an alternative way of valuing an option. We can pretend that investors are risk- neutral, so that all the assets would earn the same risk-free rate of return in equilibrium. We then discount the expected value of the option at the risk- free rate to get the current value. To do this, let R, and R, be the rate of return on the stock in each state, p be the probability that corresponds to q in the risk-neutral .world, and r be the risk-free rate. In equilibrium, the stock’s expected rate of return equals the riskless rate of return, pR,,+(1-led=r, (15) where Ru=(S,/S)-1 and R,=IS,/Sl-1. Solving for the risk-neutral probability p, gives p=_lid_=/1+rIS-Sd. (15) RU-Rd Sir—8d The current value of the option is equal to the expected payoff of the option. discounted at the rate r, (.‘= p0,, +(1-pICd. 1+r (17) The solutions for p and C are exactly the same as we derived in (13). 23 1.3. An Application to Real Investment Decisions Before we proceed with examples of how to apply the option valuation technique (OVT) to a real investment, it would be helpful to discuss its advantage over two other conventional techniques: the net-present-value method (NPV) and the decision-tree analysis (DTA). The options approach to investment is very flexible, because it encompasses the other two methods of project evaluation: The OVT draws from the NPV a technique of finding a risk-comparable portfolio, while borrowing from the DTA an idea of valuing flexibility. The NPV method first determines the expected net cash flows that a project will generate. and then discounts them with a proper rate that allows for risk inherent in the project. A typical method of determining the discount rate is to search for a hypothetical traded asset or a portfolio with the equivalent risk. The NPV method, however, does not allow for any contingencies. The initial decision to accept or reject the project is not subject to change over its entire life. The DTA, on the other hand, takes explicitly into account the interdependencies between a series of decisions. The firm's prior decisions are reevaluated at a time when new information is available. Clearly, the DTA is better than the NPV in order to reach an optimal decision over time. The problem with the DTA is that finding the appropriate risk-adjusted discount rate is very tricky, because the risk of the project alters relentlessly as contingencies affecting the project value evolve over time. As we shall see later, the OVT proves to be well suited to address both the firm’s operating flexibilities and risk adjustments. 24 Finally, the fact that a typical firm has a large pool of assets brings up an issue that deserves some attention. In valuing the firm as a whole, it is important to ask the following question beforehand: Is it justified to use the arithmetic sum of individual asset values to value the entire firm? Since diversification raises the firm value, a portfolio of assets may have a greater value than does the sum of the values of its components. If so, we may be faced by a daunting task in order to value the firm; if a diversified firm has more value, each asset has to be valued for its contribution to the firm’s portfolio of assets, not as an independent component. Fortunately, a very general concept in corporate finance comes to the rescue, namely, the principle of value additivity. The principle argues that, if the capital market is perfect, and investors can diversify their assets on their own, a firm’s diversification is redundant. and does not affect the value of the firm. That is the basis on which we can value the firm without worrying about the validity of an adding-up of individual asset values. See Brealey and Myers (1991) for a discussion of the practical importance of value additivity in various contexts. Let us now go on to the illustrative examples. The discussion will follow for two polar situations, depending on whether the firm’s output is traded. As we shall see. different replication strategies are used between these two cases. The non-traded case will discuss three sub-cases, depending on whether delaying an investment is available and whether delaying has a cost. This treatment is helpful in comparing the three different approaches of project evaluation discussed above. 25 1.3.1 . Non-Traded Output 1:hn in'n vill r nin Consider a firm’s problem of investing in a single new project over the next two periods. Suppose that that: A) the firm cannot delay the investment, so the investment decision should made in the first period; 8) the project yields in the second period a revenue equal to either V,,= $150 or V,,= $100, with an equal probability q=0.5; and C) the project requires an initial expenditure equal to K= $110. Since this project is completely new to the firm, we may not use the firm's (weighted) average cost of capital (WACC). The standard net-present- value (NPV) method tells us that, in order to determine the correct discount rate, we must find an asset or a portfolio that has the same risk characteristics with the project under consideration, and is currently traded. Suppose that this replicating asset has the expected payoffs equal to Su=30 and Sd=20 in each state, and currently priced at 8: $21. Note that the asset's payoff is proportional to that of the project: V,/S,,= V/S,,=5. Hence we can use the discount rate of the asset, because they have the same risk. Denoting the discount rate by p. the standard NPV formula is written as S= qSu +(1-qISd . (18) 1+ p Solving for p and plugging in the associated numbers yields p=qs"+"-qlsd-1=O.19. (19) S 26 This is the discount rate we are seeking. The NPV of the project is then computed according to = 0V, +II—qIV, 1+p NPVS ~K=$105-$110=$-5. (20) The simple NPV method recommends that the project should be rejected. Let us now value the project using the option valuation technique (OVT). It is intuitively obvious that the OVT will produce the same result, since there is no option embedded in the project. As we have seen in the last section, the OVT uses the hypothetical risk-neutral probability p, in place of the actual probability q, in valuing an asset. Assuming the risk-free interest rate r=0.1, p can be computed from equation (16). =(7+f}S-Sd =o.31. (21) Su —Sd Using p as the weight probability, the net present value of the project is pV,,+(1—pr, 7+r NPV,= —K=$105-$110=$-5. (22) This is exactly the same value as we have computed in equation (20). I i i v il w' h When a delay of the investment is possible. the firm must extend its planning horizon. and decide the optimal timing of investment over the two periods. In the diagram below, E, and E, denote the net payoffs from the optimal investment decision in the second period; it earns a net payoff of $29 by investing in the good state, while it earns nothing by giving up 27 investing in bad state. V,= $105 is the expected gross payoff from the investment undertaken in first period as in equation (20). when the investment is made in the first period. The firm first calculates the expected net payoff from the optimal decision in the second period, and then compares it with the expected net payoff from the optimal decision in the first period to decide whether and when to invest. WK; $150;E,,=Max[V,,-l1 +r)K.0]= $29 V,=$105, E,=? (K=$110) \ 1-q=0.5 V,=$100;E,=Max[V,-(1 +r)K,0]=$0. In effect, this is exactly what the decision-tree analysis (DTA) asks us to do. In a more complicated case, the DTA enables us to work through all the decision nodes to reach a best solution. To compute the expected payoff from the optimal decision in the second period, we determine the appropriate discount rate. Note that the discount rate derived in the Jorgensonian case above (p=0.19) is not valid, since the newly characterized investment opportunity is no longer correlated with the replicating portfolio used there. Unfortunately, there is no way the DTA can solve this problem. Hence we ought to find a replicating portfolio using the NPV, and get a risk-neutral probability p. In our case, p is already computed in equation (21) as ___ (1+r/S-S, su—Sd =O.31. (23) 28 It is now obvious why the OVT combines the principles of the DTA and the NPV. The present value of the investment opportunity is calculated as the weighted value of E, and E,, discounted by the riskless interest rate r, pEu + (1 —p)E, NPV": 1+r =$8.2. (24) The OVT suggests that the project should not be rejected. The example shows that the value of a project can be enhanced by waiting and making an investment decision in the second period. The difference between NPV, in equation (24) and NPV, in equation (20) is a value addition achieved by waiting, V,=NPV,-NPV,=$8.2-($-5)=$13.2. (25) The basic principle of the option valuation enables us to value the flexibility in the firm's investment decisions. :Wn Iini v'llwih We now introduce a cost of waiting in our example. Suppose that. if the firm were to wait, it would lose in the current period a value equal to a constant proportion 6 of the value of the project.9 Assuming that 6:0.1, the expected payoffs of the second period would be E,=Max[(1-8)V,-(1+rIK, 0]=$18.7. (26) and E,=Max[(1-6) V,-(7 +rlK, 0]: $0. (27) 9 The lost valued is assumed, for simplicity, to be exogenous. Needless to say, we can endogenlze it by rendering it dependent on other variables. 29 Working through the same steps from (23) through (25). we obtain Su -Sd NPv,=pE"+"’p’Ed =$5.3, (29) 1+r and V,=NPV,-NPV,=$5.3-($-5)=$10.3. (30) In this case, waiting is still optimal, although the value of waiting has decreased. In other cases where the cost of waiting is sufficiently large, it would be desirable to undertake an investment in the first period.10 1.3.2. Traded Output‘1 When a firm’s project produces an output that is traded in the market, an investment opportunity—that is, an option to invest in the future— is perfectly correlated with the output price. Hence the firm's output is the underlying asset of the option to invest in the future. so a risk-hedging portfolio can be constructed using the option and the output without a need to find another twin asset. Consider a firm that is planning a single project that is irreversible. Assume that the project produces one unit of output each period indefinitely, and the initial investment expenditure, K= $500, is the only cost. Suppose that the current price of output is Po: $80, but it will either rise to P,= $120 or fall to P,= $40 with equal probability q=0.5 1° For example, we can calculate the critical value of 8=0.31 at which V,=0. Doing an investment immediately is optimal, when 6 exceeds that level. '1 The example in this section is based on Dixit and Pindyck (1994), Chap. 2. 30 over the next period, and will remain the same forever. We assume that the firm behaves as if it were risk-neutral by eliminating the market risk of the project through diversification.12 As in the last example. let us solve the firm’s optimal investment decision problem under different assumptions. The first solution does not allow for waiting. Letting v, denote the present discounted value of cash flows from the project, and assuming that the interest rate r=0.1, the NPV of the project is co fl-K: 1+ (1+ 1’ r’P,-K=$330, (31) r=1 r NPV, = v,-K=P,+ since the expected price of P from the next period onward is EIP,I =P, =$80. When waiting is allowed, the solution must again go through the following two steps: first, we calculate the NPV from the optimal decision in the next period, when the information on the output price is available. Next, we compare it with the NPV from the optimal decision in the current period, and make the final decision from the perspective of the entire planning horizon. In effect, this is the solution technique of a two-period dynamic programming problem. Algebraically, the NPV is obtained by solving 1 +r NPv,=Max{lv,-K, 7 5,1511}. (32) where EOIFJ is the expected net payoff from the optimal second-period decision. Evaluating the second term of (32) gives ‘2 This assumption is needed to keep the firm's risk preference from affecting the 31 1 °° P (1+r/K] (P j “—5 F = ” — = —"—K =$350. (33) 1+r 0/ ') q(;(1+r)‘ (1+r) q r SinceVo-K= $330 from (31). solving equation (32) yields NPV,=Max[330. 350]=$350. As before, the difference between NPV, and NPV, is a value-added by waiting, V,=NPV,-NPV,= $20, (34) When waiting is allowed, we can obtain the same solution using the option valuation technique. To show this, let V: be the NPV of the investment opportunity, and V; and V}, be those binomial values of the investment opportunity valued in each state from the optimal decision in the next period. Depending on the movement of the price in the next period, V; and V), are expressed as V; =Max(-1+—r-Pu -I7+r)K, 0) = $770 (35) r V; =Max(1:r Pd -/1+r)K, 0) = $0. (36) Now that we have contingency values of the project in the next period, we can construct a risk-hedging portfolio by holding a long position for one unit of the option to invest, and holding a short position for N units of the output. We now need to impose two requirements in equilibrium to ensure that there are no arbitrage opportunities: The first and familiar one is that option value. See footnote 8. 32 the portfolio must yield the riskless rate of return in any state. The second and new one is that we ought to pay a compensation to other investors to induce them to hold a long position for the output.13 The compensation should be made at the riskless rate of return, because we assume that systematic risk is diversified away, and the expected price of output equals the current price that is constant (EIP,) =Po). Mathematically, this arbitrage condition is written as v;,, -NP,-rNPo=(1+r)(Vf-NP0). (37) and Vd’d-NP,-rNP0=(1+r)(Vf-NP0). (38) The term rNPo is the compensation made to other investors. Letting P,=uP, and P,=dPo,, and solving these equation for V: gives a: 1-d " (1+r/(u-dl [’t’up, —(1+rlK) =s350. (39) The option to invest has the same value that we have derived in (33). In our example. the dynamic programming and the option valuation techniques produce the same numerical result. In effect, they are equivalent in valuing any options on investment. even though they are based on different solution concepts. Both of the solutions suggest that waiting and deciding to invest in the next period has a greater value than immediate investing. We can also interpret our result from a different perspective. The NPV from the myopic decision is $330, while the NPV from the flexible ‘3 In the last example, we do not need this requirement, since the underlying asset is the financial asset traded in the market, so the compensation is already reflected in the 33 decision is $350. Hence. if the firm makes the myopic decision, it will lose $350. which is the value of the option to invest in the next available period. This lost value should be added to the opportunity cost of immediate investing. The total cost of investing today, therefore, is K+ NPV,= $500 + $350 = $850. which is greater than the gross benefit of investing today, V,=K+NPV,= $500 + $330 = $830. The explicit consideration of the option suggests that investing in the current period should be rejected. The foregoing discussion implies that the firm has three possibilities in its investment decisions; it will never invest. or wait until the next period, or invest now. depending on the current output price, P,. The critical values of P, are determined by investigating whether NPV,$0 and NPV,SNPV,.“ Imposing these conditions on equations (31) and (39), and solving for P, gives two critical values of P,, which divide the optimal investment rule into three phases: if P,S$33.3, it is never optimal to invest in either period since the project has a negative NPV; if P,>$47, it is optimal invest now since waiting is costly; and if P, is in-between, it is optimal to wait since waiting is valuable. We can also do some comparative statics to investigate how each variable affects the value of the option to invest. The most interesting asset price in equilibrium. ‘4 The equality in NPvdsNPV, is called the ‘value matching condition' , which is used to obtain a critical value of Pa. When the time is continuous, an additional condition, 34 variable would be the uncertainty over the output price. We can use (u-dl as a measure of uncertainty, because a greater value of this is translated into a more volatile movement of the price in the next period. Partially differentiating V: with respect to (u-d) gives (+) (+) (+) 6V" 1+r 1+r BTU—5717 =(u-7l (TuP, - (1+r/K) +(u-dll7-dl-7—UP0 >0: which shows that V," is positively related with uncertainty. This results from the fact that the firm has the flexibility of admitting upside gains. while dismissing downside losses. by obtaining information about price in the next period. Waiting may be the firm’s optimal decision in response to irreversibility of its investment. This also implies that behind the option value lie asymmetries in the firm’s behavior; see Dixit and Pindyck (1994), Chap. 2, for other interesting comparative static results. The basic message of our discussion is that a positive net present value of a project does not necessarily warrant the acceptance of an investment. When the investment decision is irreversible, it eventually involves the option to wait and decide in the next available period. This flexibility has a value that is to be lost. when the firm decides to invest now. The option value must, therefore, be added to the cost of an immediate investment. One qualification is in order; options may work in a perverse way. Waiting called the “smooth pasting condition”, is required at that critical value to ensure a continuous differentlability. We will discuss these conditions again later on. 35 may induce a substantial cost to firms. For example, by delaying an investment, the existing firm may encourage other competing firms to undertake a preemptive investment, so the firm's growth options and value would be seriously affected by this possibility. 0n the other hand, an early investment may reveal valuable information that is crucial to a firm’s future profitability. Marketing, advertising, and R&D expenditures are examples. In whatever characteristics options may have. the naive net present value method does not allow for these possibilities. Our simple illustration provides a persuasive case for casting a skeptical view of the standard approach to optimal investment decisions. By employing such elegant techniques as dynamic programming or contingency claim analysis, the new approach would offer a better alternative in capturing options and providing useful interpretations. Chapter 2 Uncertainty, Irreversibility, and Tax Policy 2.1. Introduction Theoretical developments to study the firm’s investment decision have been enriched by recent research programs, stressing the firm’s uncertain environment and rigidities in adjusting the capital stock. New theories have provided valuable insights into the conventional cost-of—capital approach, and the q-theory of investment: the firm’s cost of capital, and q are no longer static. The literature on irreversible investment has found that the firm’s investment process is characterized by the option value, hysteresis (inertia), and dynamics of rational expectations. These studies have also offered good empirical models to better explain the observable behavior of the firms' investment in a more realistic setting.‘ Incorporating taxes into these investment models with uncertainty and rigidity appears to be a promising research agenda. Nevertheless, few attempts have been made so far. Along the line of the standard neoclassical theory, Bernheim and Shoven (1989) employ a capital asset pricing model (CAPM) to address the importance of uncertainty and risk. They find that risk premia are a very important component of the cost of capital, and that the U.S. corporate tax system discriminates against risky investment ‘ There is a large amount of literature devoted to these research efforts. See the survey articles by Dixit (1992) and Pindyck (1991). Dixit and Pindyck (1994) is their co-authored book, which provides a systematic treatment of the new approach to the firm's capital decisions. 36 37 projects. In order to treat taxes, risk, and interest rates simultaneously, they use a highly stylized neoclassical investment problem that permits firms to adjust the capital stock instantaneously. MacKie-Mason (1989) studies an interaction between non-linearities in the tax system and uncertainty in a framework of irreversibility investment. He employs a stochastic equilibrium model popularized in financial economics. It is a well-established result that the value of a future investment opportunity under uncertainty is significant, so that it is optimal for firms to delay the investment. unless immediate profitability from the investment is sufficiently high to compensate for this lost value of the option to wait; see, for example. McDonald and Siegel (1986). Their introduction of non-linearities in taxes yields a surprising result that the government’s role of risk-sharing by taxing firms may encourage investment.2 While the work of MacKie-Mason is an application of the Black-Scholes model of financial options, McKenzie (1994), and Hassett and Metcalf (1994) adopt a dynamic programming approach to irreversible investment to consider the effects of taxes.3 McKenzie calculates the marginal effective tax rates for major Canadian industries, using a model of irreversible investment. The rates are found to be increasing in both market and specific risk. He concludes that the tax system in Canada is distorted against risky 2 This argument is analogous to one propoSed by Gordon (1985). Yet they differ in the nature of the risk addressed. Risk is commonly classified into two types: firm- specific (unsystematic) and aggregate (market or systematic). Gordon's risk sharing is concerned with market risk only, while Mackie-Mason considers both market and specific risk. 3 Bertola (1988) shows that two approaches are equivalent in essence, only differing in the assumption about the tradability of risk in the financial market. See Dixit and Pindyck (1994), Chap. 4, for a discussion. 38 capital to a greater extent, when irreversibility is explicitly considered. The Hassett and Metcalf study focuses on uncertainty over tax policy as well as over the output price. Specifically, they model a random movement of the investment tax credit to examine the effect of tax policy changes on investment. Interestingly enough. they argue that different assumptions about tax uncertainty may have contradicting conclusions: when uncertainty over tax policy is modeled as a continuous random walk process, which is popular in most studies. increasing uncertainty discourages investment. 0n the other hand, when uncertainty is modeled as a jump (Poisson) process, an increase in uncertainty stimulates investment. In this chapter, we examine the effectiveness of tax policy in a model of investment uncertainty and irreversibility. We extend existing studies in two directions. First, we adopt a more realistic assumption on the firm's irreversibility in investment. Following Dixit (1989), a firm’s investment is partially reversible, so that it has the option to abandon the project as well as the option to invest. Other tax models of irreversible investment —-including McKenzie (1994) and Hassett and Metcalf (1994). cited above—usually do not allow for partial reversibility. These models, therefore, are inadequate in examining the role of irreversibility at various levels. In the present model, we can carefully identify the effects of tax policy under different degrees of irreversibility. Also, by taking an eclectic position between the standard neoclassical model assuming complete reversibility. and the standard irreversibility investment model assuming a complete irreversibility, we are in a better position to connect two views. 39 Second. most existing studies focus on deriving the optimal investment rule by solving a firm’s optimization problem. We will go beyond that by simulating the aggregate investment behaviors based on the optimal investment rule. These simulations are useful in verifying the model's validity in predicting the actual behavior of investment. In doing so, we introduce a simple heterogeneity in the degree of irreversibility of firms; firms are differ in their capabilities in reversing their investments. Modeling the heterogeneous characters across firms has increasingly been employed by investment theorists. This strategy allows us to point to the fact that only a fraction of them alter their investments in response to a shock over time.‘ We begin by providing in Section 2 a little essential mathematical background for stochastic processes, and stochastic calculus. Section 3 presents a simple dynamic model of a firm's investment decisions under uncertainty and irreversibility. We solve the model by dynamic programming techniques. and interpret the resulting solutions for the value of the firm in terms of the options. We also derive a refined version of the cost-of-capital formula, and discuss its relationship to the Jorgensonian formula. In section 4, we conduct a sensitivity analysis to examine the effects of taxes. uncertainty. and irreversibility on the cost of capital. Since closed-form solutions are not available for the model, we present numerical results I instead. In section 5, we introduce a structure of heterogeneity in the firms ‘ Some recent models employ a more elegant method of modeling the firm's heterogeneity by using, for example, an adjustment hazard function. The partial adjustment model, or the standard (S, s) adjustment model is a special form of the hazard function. See Caballero and Engel (1992) for these modeling efforts. 40 irreversibility of investment, and perform simulations to generate the aggregate investment behavior. The simulation results are presented for both costless and costly reversibility. and for varying parameter values for the tax system, uncertainty, and irreversibility, to facilitate comparisons. Section 6 is concluding remarks. 2.2. Mathematical Preliminaries 2.2.1. Stochastic Processes and Brownian Motion A stochastic process deals with a system which evolves according to a specified probabilistic law. To model uncertainty properly, we must assume a specific random process which underlies the variables in question. One example is a discrete-time random walk with drift which evolves according to x,-x,-, =p+s,, (1) where p represents the trend, and a, a white noise, or a random variable drawn from the normal distribution with mean zero and unit variance. In the limit as the time interval goes to zero, the discrete-time random walk takes a process of the (absolute) Brownian motion with drift, dx=,udt+a'dw, ' (2) where dw=s,, Els,)=0, and Var(3,) = 1. w is the standardized Wiener process whose increment dw has mean zero and variance dt. Similar to its discrete equivalent, p represents the trend, and a the volatility of the process. Note that x has a normal distribution. so EIdx)=pdt. and 41 Varldx)=a’dt. Over an infinitesimal time interval dt, the Brownian motion evolves with mean ,udt and variance azdt. Since this Brownian motion measures the changes in x in absolute terms, x can take a negative value. If we need to restrict x to positive . . dx values, we can assume Instead that the relatIve change of x, —, has a x normal distribution to prevent x from being negative.5 Thus we have the geometric Brownian motion with drift, 2’: =,udt+a’dw. (3) x This stochastic process is widely used in the empirical analysis of asset prices and exchange rates. etc. Ignoring the volatility term. we are left with an ordinary differential equation, dx — = X, (4) dt [1 which has the solution. X =Xoeflt, (5) where x, is the initial value of x at t=t,,. Thus, the geometric Brownian motion combines continuous-time dynamics with uncertainty in a mathematically tractable way. It is useful in addressing many typical stochastic settings in economics and finance. 5 This modification is also necessary because, if the absolute change. dx. is normally distributed, a variation of 1 percent is more significant at low base than at high base. Hence we need to weight dx by the level value. x. 42 2.2.2. Ito's Lemma When we differentiate the functions of a Brownian motion, ordinary calculus is not readily applicable due to the existence of the volatility term. Consider a stochastic function, y=f(x), where x is a random variable that follows a process of the absolute Brownian motion of equation (2). When there is no volatility term, the function fix) is deterministic, so we can apply Taylor’s theorem to obtain dy = f’lxldx + gf'lxlldxlz + = f ’(xlpdt+ oldt). (6) where oldt) is the sum of higher-order terms in dt that will disappear, when dt goes to zero. This is the basis of ordinary differentiation. When we reintroduce the volatility term, -21-f'(xlldx12. the second term in the first equation above, has a term that involves a square of dw=s,\(dt . Since the order of this term is dt, we must consider this term in differentiation. Expanding flx} using the Taylor series expansion yields dy = f’lxldx + %f'lxl rdx)’ + = f’IxH/zdt + qdw) + %f’(xl(pdt + a'dwl’ + (7) Using the fact that Eldwl=0, and Varldw) =Eildwlzl =dt. and SUDPFBSSINQ the higher terms in dt. the stochastic function dy has mean Eldy) = [f’lxlp + é-f'lxlazldt. 43 and variance Varldyl = [f’fxl alzdt. Recalling that E(dx) =pdt and Varldx) =q’dt in the absolute Brownian motion, dx=pdt+adw, y follows another process of Brownian motion, dy = [f’(x)p+ éf”lx}02]dt+ f’lxladw. (8) When x follows the geometric Brownian motion of equation (3), we can derive, by taking similar steps. dy= [f’Ixpr-I- -;—f”(xlx20"]dt+f'lxlxa'dw. (9) This is a basic result of ltO’s Lemma. In a nutshell, Ito's Lemma is to a function of random variables what Taylor's theorem is to a function of deterministic variables. Hence the lemma is used to differentiate a function of a random variable with respect to the random variable itself. In ltO's Lemma, the second moment of a distribution plays an important role. The sign of this term, %f”lxlaz, is dependent on the curvature of the function, fix). It is the consequence of Jensen's inequality, which relates the expected value of a function of a random variable, Elflxll, with the value of the function of the expected value of the random variable, flEfxll; if the function is strictly convex (concave). the former (latter) is greater than the latter (former), so that [fix/I) flElxll. (10) 44 A good example of a convexity case is the profit function. Let fix) be a profit function. and x be the output price. It is well-known from the microeconomic principle that fix) is convex in x. Suppose that a firm faces x that is fluctuating randomly, as in the case of the Brownian motion process. Then, the inequality relationship (10) implies that the firm can expect more profits by producing a flexible output in response to fluctuating prices, rather than by producing a fixed output at the average price. In this simple example, flexibility has a value; see Varian (1992), Chap. 3, for more discussion on this. 2.2.3. Application of Ité’s Lemma Since ItO’s Lemma is so important in working with any function of the Brownian motion, we will present two functional forms frequently used in economics: see Dixit (1993) for more general treatment. The first one is of the form fix)=expi/ix), where x follows the absolute Brownian motion. Applying ltO's Lemma of equation (8) gives df= Iiexprixip + % Azexprzxiaidt + .iexprzxiadw = fix/(.1). + glzazldt + flxuadw, (1 1 ) which can be rewritten as f’fI. =12,” éfl’a’]dt+ladw. (12) 45 This is nothing other than a form of the geometric Brownian motion. Since fixl=expilxl is convex, we have a positive term, £1202. As an application to the geometric Brownian motion, suppose that fix)=x‘, where x follows the geometric Brownian motion. Using ltO’s Lemma of equation (9). we can write df as df= [Ax-u“ é/lil— rixi-Zx’azidt+2.xi-'xadw, (13) which can be rewritten as 5:1 = [241+ gill-lmzlduzadw. (14) Observe that fix) also follows the geometric Brownian motion; see Dixit and Pindyck (1994), Chap. 3, for more discussion. 2.3. The Basic Model The model closely follows the work of Avinash Dixit (1989). which analyzes a firm's entry and exit decisions under uncertainty. A representative firm is infinitely lived, and has a single stand-alone monopolized project to invest in.° The firm produces one unit of output at each unit of time. The firm’s uncertainty is over demand, so that, given the firm's fixed flow of output, price uncertainty corresponds directly to demand ° Another modeling strategy is to consider an incremental investment. This would allow for a more flexible treatment of a firm’s production and adjustment technology, but at the sacrifice of simplicity of the model. See Abel and Eberly (1996) for a model along this line. 46 uncertainty, and is considered to be exogenous. The firm can purchase a unit of capital at a lump-sum price E, when investing, and can sell it at a lump- sum price R, when disinvesting. We assume RsE, to exclude a costless arbitrage opportunity. In other words. part of the capital expenditure is irreversible and is considered sunk, when R1 I32 =é-i1-tlir-5l/az-Jli1- rlir — a) / 0'2 - £12 + 2m - r) / a" < o. ‘2 Notice that this method is closely related with the risk-neutral probability method discussed in section 1.2 of Chapter 1. It was first pr0posed by Constantinides (1978). Its theoretical results are based on the intertemporal CAPM analysis pioneered by Merton (1973). Brealey and Myers (1991), Chap. 9, provides a simple exposition of how to use the CAPM to calculate a certainty equivalent. ‘3 Denoting the expression in bracket in equation (25) by Difl), we can see that 0(0) =-rii-r)<0, and 0(1) =-6i1-r)<0. This implies that one root is greater than 1, and the other is less than 0. 52 Since the two roots are real and distinct, the complementary function is V,‘iP)=A,P”' +A2P’2, (26) where A, and A, remain to be determined. The particular integral can be obtained by the method of undetermined coefficients. The obvious form of the solution would be V,iP)=B,P-B,C, so that V,’iP)=B, and V,"(P)=0. Substituting these into equation (24) and collecting terms, we get JB,P-rB,C = P-C. (27) Equating both sides term by term gives 8, = 7/5 and 8,: i/r. Thus, the particular integral is V,” (P) = P/6- C/r. (28) Finally, we can combine the complementary function and the particular integral to obtain the complete solution, V,iP) =A,P’i #1,)”32 +P/6-C/r. (29) This equation has a straightforward economic interpretation. The last two terms of the right-hand side are the particular integral. They stand for the fundamental value of the (investing) firm that stems from the expected net cash flows. The first two terms are the complementary function. They stand for the value of the option to exit that must be added to the fundamental value of the firm. If the investment is completely irreversible, 53 the option to exit will disappear, leaving only the fundamental value of the firm. This option value becomes worthless at a higher level of P, since it is less likely that P will drop to the critical level, P,, that induces the firm to exit. At an extreme, where P goes to co, the value of the option goes to zero. Yet the first term of (29) goes to 00 as P goes to 00, because fl,> 1. This implies that A, should be zero. Thus, the imposition of a limiting condition at P=oo yields the value of the investing firm, V,iP) =A2Pfiz +P/6—C/r, for P>PU. (so) The value of a disinvesting firm, V,iP). can be derived in a similar manner. We can think of it as the mirror image of the investing firm; if the firm exits, it gains the option to invest, while losing the operating profits. Its value is the option to invest only. Similarly to equation (17), the value of the disinvesting firm is written as V,iP) = e"”"""E[V,iP+ dP)]. (31 ) Taking similar steps as before, we have a differential equation. .2. 02P2V,'(P) + i1-r)ir-6)PV,’iPl-ri1-tl V,iP) = o. (31) Note that this equation has only the homogenous part. Solving for V, gives V,iP) =B,P”' +32)”. (32) The two terms on the right-hand side stand for the option to invest. This option value becomes worthless at a lower level of P, since it is less likely that P will rise to the critical level, P,, that induces the firm to invest. At a extreme, where P goes to zero. the value of the option goes to zero. Yet the 54 second term of (32) goes to 00 as P goes to 0, because ,6,<0. This implies that B, should be zero. We are now left with the value of the disinvesting firm, V,iP)=B,Pfi', for PP,,, (38) V,iP) =3, P“, for P c +rE (since W'iP,) < 0). (47) Similarly at P,, we have, P, = c + rR- 2 1: I) a’Pf W'iP,) < c + rR (since W'iP,) > 0). (48) Equations (47) and (48) imply that P,R; a' and r vary. This is a more general case of costly reversibility. Figure 2.2 and Table 2.2 illustrate the effects of reducing the selling price of capital from 2.0 to R: 1.9. We can see that even a small sunk cost has a significant effect on the cost of capital. The picture also shows that the effect of uncertainty dominates that of the tax throughout the whole range. At a higher level of uncertainty, the region of inaction is substantially widened. The base-case simulation in the table shows that P, increases by 0.04, and P, decreases by 0.03, respectively, as r rises from 0 to 0.5. On the contrary, P, rises by 0.34, and P, falls by 0.23, respectively, in response to the corresponding change in c. ‘° This can be confirmed by the graph below. WiP) passes a point of inflection at PM=Oo88. mp) 10 7.5 5 2.5 p .25. 0.5 1 1 5 2 -5: -7,5. -10. 62 Figure (Table) 2.2 - Effect of Taxes and Uncertainty on the Threshold 1.9) n: I =2 Prices (Costly Reversibility: E 63 = 0.2' n tv r. In this case, we fix the uncertainty, while varying irreversibility and the tax rate. Figures (Tables) 2.3 and 2.4 show the results for two values of uncertainty: 0:0 and a=0.2. Table 2.3 shows that irreversibility only affect the lower threshold price, P,, even under perfect certainty, implying that the firm is more reluctant to exit when the investment cost recovery is smaller. In the base-line simulation, P, falls from 0.88 to 0.84 by reducing R to 1.0 from 2.0. The tax rate changes, however, have no effect at any level of irreversibility. Adding uncertainty alters the picture in a significant way, as we can see from the comparison of Figure 2.3 with Figure 2.4. In Table 2.4, the base-line calculation shows that, compared with the Marshallian benchmark of 0.88, P, increases by 0.40 to 1.28 and P, reduces by 0.28 to 0.60, respectively as E reduces to 1.0 from 2.0 The tax rate changes do have an effect under uncertainty, but their magnitudes are moderate; the resulting changes in the threshold prices are less than 0.1 in most ranges of R. The striking feature of Figure 2.4 is that even a small change in irreversibility has a strong effect on the firm’s cost of capital, especially at a lower level of irreversibility. This observation is reminiscent of a famous argument found in the menu cost literature. Menu costs refer to the costs of changing prices. For example, a firm may need to send out new catalogues to announce the price changes of its products, which incurs some costs to the firm. Menu cost models were originally developed to explain price stickiness in the short run. 64 Figure (Table) 2.3 - Effect of Taxes and Irreversibility on the Threshold Prices (Certainty Case: a= 0) 65 Figure (Table) 2.4 - Effect of Taxes and Irreversibility on the Threshold Prices (Uncertainty Case: a=0.2) . s . . . A . .2 9' $2. ... . o C , . e . 2 . . . . . . . s s . . .. . . 3 v. 66 The basic idea of these models is that prices do not adjust immediately since there are costs involved in changing prices. Sticky prices, in turn, lead to a large economic disturbance because small costs of adjustment induce a wide range of inertia: if it is optimal for firms not to change prices, nominal prices will not adjust. and monetary policy will affect output. When a firm's capital decisions are costly to reverse, the optimal rule for investment, or disinvestment, also involves a range of inaction. The firm would make an investment decision only when profitability is especially good, and would reverse its decision only when profitability becomes especially bad. There is an intermediate range where a status quo is optimal.17 Finally, it would be an interesting experiment to calculate the tax equivalent of an increase in uncertainty, since 1 and c act together to change the threshold prices through their effects on ,3. Specifically, we set R=1.9, and r=0.3, and calculate the threshold prices by increasing a by 0.05 at a time from each benchmark value of 0.2 to 0.5. Then we work backwards to calculate the tax rate required to obtain the same threshold prices, with a being set to benchmark values. Table 2.5 shows the result. Let us take a figure, say, 38.9 from the first column, to give an interpretation. This number means that we need a 38.9 percent increase in the tax rate to get the same effect that we would get from raising a- from ‘7 The early menu-cost models are static. In these models, a second-order menu cost causes first-order effects. See, for example, Mankiw (1985). Using a dynamic menu cost model, Dixit (1991b) shows rigorously that the fourth-order small cost of change generates first-order inertia. 67 Table 2.5 - Tax Equivalent of an Increase in Uncertainty (percent. R=1.9) benchmark a increment in a 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.05 25.2 18.6 14.7 12.1 0.1 38.9 30.6 25.2 21.4 0.15 47.1 38.9 33.0 28.6 0.2 52.5 49.2 38.9 34.3 0.25 56.2 44.8 43.5 38.9 0.3 58.8 52.5 47.1 42.7 Source: Author's calculations 0.2 to 0.3. If we take a=0.3 as a benchmark, the corresponding increase in the tax rate required to get the same effect of raising a from 0.3 to 0.4 is 30.6 percent. From this experiment, we can infer that, if the economy is experiencing a smaller volatility, a stronger tax incentive may be needed to offset a certain amount of volatility. On the other hand, if the economy is highly volatile. a less strong tax incentive would be enough to offset the same amount of volatility. Two implications follow for tax policy from our analysis. First, the conditions for the tax neutrality in the standard models need to be reexamined. It is well documented that expensing of capital expenditure, or allowing for economic depreciation, will lead to a neutral tax system, depending on interest deductibility. Yet as we have already seen, a profit tax is no longer neutral under irreversible investment. If we ignore this 68 possibility, tax policy might be designed in a non-optimal way. It would, therefore, be a worthwhile effort to reexamine the standard proposition on neutrality of taxes by allowing for more complexities.18 Second, we have already shown that even a profit tax may affect the firm's investment decision. Yet its effect ought to be examined in the context of other considerations like irreversibility and uncertainty. The driving force of the present model is the effects on the value of the options of these key parameters. An option has a greater value. the more flexibly the firm behaves and the higher the uncertainty is. This implies that asymmetries (irreversibility) and uncertainty in the economy or in the tax system might have a stronger effect than might the level of taxes.19 Also, if firms are in the region of inaction between P, and P,, it is optimal for them to make no move. The problem with this is that the government is likely to step in and use tax incentives to stimulate investment, although it is not an Optimal intervention. The government should be cautious in distinguishing between these two elusive situations. Even if the case of the optimal intervention is correctly identified, fine-tuning the investment through tax instruments would be a tough task, in the sense that the region of inaction is a very dynamic one, so it is also a region of ignorance. The implication is that it is almost impossible to conduct tax policy by discretion by taking whatever policy seems appropriate at each time. The best policy option would be to ‘3 Abel (1983a) is an attempt along this line of research in the presence of adjustment costs in investment. See also Hartman (1978). " We already mentioned two works along these lines. Hassett and Metcalf (1994) introduce random taxes into a model similar to ours. MacKie-Mason (1994) studies an interaction between non-linearities in the tax system and uncertainty, in a stochastic equilibrium model a la Black and Scholes (1973). 69 announce in advance how policy will respond to various contingencies. This is why the second-best rule-based tax policy deserves further consideration under uncertainty and irreversible investment. 2.5. Simulation of Investment Behavior In the previous section, we have derived a firm's optimal rule of investment. To reiterate, the optimal behavior of the firm comprises three regimes: (i) the firm will invest. if P is greater than P,; (ii) the firm will neither invest nor disinvest. if P is between P, and P,; and (iii) the firm will disinvest, if P is less than P,. It would be useful and interesting to use our investment decision model for simulations of aggregate investment behavior. The first step of doing this work is to generate a sample path of the output price from the assumed stochastic process. Figure 2.5 is a sample path of the price over 150 months to be used for simulation. The underlying stochastic process is a discrete version of the geometric Brownian that evolves according to P,=Pr-r +0.0577P2-r 5:! where P,=0.88, and a, “N(0,1).2° 2° A time interval taken is of one month, and the starting value, P,=0.88, is the standard Marshallian threshold price discussed earlier. This process has only a volatility term with q=0.2 per year. Its monthly equivalent, therefore, is 02.2 /12 =o.os77. output price (14 015 (16 0(7 (18 (19 L2 L3 L4 1A L0 70 WW“ 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130 140 150 time Figure 2.5 - A Sample Path of Output Price 71 When there are many firms, each of them will at each point of time observe the output price and decide whether to invest. stay, or disinvest, according to its own optimal decision rule. Once investing or disinvesting is undertaken, firms are free to reverse their actions, but with incurring the same cost of entry and exit again. Simulations are performed for 300 firms that are identical except for the selling price of capital, R; we assume that R is normally distributed across firm, with mean and variance to vary across simulations. The simple structure of firm heterogeneity will allow us to highlight the role of irreversibility. For the purpose of comparison, we first conduct a simulation without assuming firm heterogeneity, that is. by assuming that investment is costlessly reversible for every firm. Figure 2.6 shows the result. We can see a bang-bang pattern in the investment rate, calculated as the number of currently active firms divided by the total number of firms. As discussed before, these firms have the single Marshallian threshold price, P=0.88. In other words. there exists no region of inaction. Thus, when the output price goes up even slightly above it, all firms will rush into an investment. On the contrary, when the price goes down even slightly below it, all firms will rush out of the investment; the investment rate rises immediately to 100 percent in the former case, and falls to zero percent in the latter. To simulate a case of heterogeneous irreversibility across firm, we assume that the selling price of capital, R, is normally distributed with mean 1.8 and standard deviation 0.2." The result is exhibited in Figure 2.7. 2‘ But, when the randomly generated values were greater than 2, they were truncated to 2, because R.Max[Ei.)] by Jensen's inequality. ‘ We assume here that the revenue depends solely on the output price, which is stochastic only in the second period. Then the firm observes the price at the beginning of the second period, determines R,, and decides whether to invest. 86 government for each case. When the firm makes a myopic decision of investing solely in the first period, the government can take advantage of contingencies in the second period due to the lack of a loss offset; the tax authorities receive the tax claim on the firm’s profits, while avoiding the tax refund on its losses. The term, %rE{Max[R,,0]}}, in equation (2) reflects this option value. When the firm has the flexibility of waiting, the ball is with the firm. It will tailor the investment decision to its advantage by responding optimally to contingencies. After observing the after-tax cash flow in the second period, it will decide to proceed with the investment, only if the NPV in (3) is positive. Obviously, the firm's optimal decision is the one that has the larger positive value between these two choices, NPV, and NPV,.5 The difference between NPV, and NPV, is the value of waiting, or the opportunity cost of investing in the first period. This additional cost, which the traditional approach ignores. must be included in calculating the true cost of capital for an immediate investment. If the value of waiting is greater, the firm has a smaller incentive to invest immediately. The investment in the first period is warranted only when this opportunity cost of investing is equal to or less than zero. Subtracting (2) from (3), we can express the value of waiting, W, as a function of R,, win.) = T17 E{Max[l:—' i1-r)R,-K, 0]} + rMale,, 01 5 Notice that, if NPV, <0, investing in the second period is always preferred, because NPV, is always positive. 87 1+r r + {} rEiMale,, 0])-K}- R, (4) The expression (4) has two expected values of the maximum functions, E{Max[-l-::i1-r)R,-K, 0]} and E{Max[R,, 0]}. These terms are not easy to r evaluate. because they are functions of the stochastic variable, R,. Let us first consider the latter one. Since R, is normally distributed with mean R, and variance 0*, and Male,,0] is bounded from below, we ought to use the censored normal distribution to compute its expected value.“ To do so, we need to define a new random variable, 3* =0 if R,<0 R*=R2 if R220. R" is called a lower-censored normal variable. E{Max[R,,0]} is equivalent to its expected value. ElR‘], which can be calculated using the formula, EIR *1 =sis)) + a’¢is). (5) where s is a censoring point; p is the mean; ¢(.) is the probability distribution function (p.d.f.); and CPI.) is the cumulative distribution function (c.d.f.) of the uncensored variable R,, respectively. Given the censoring point s=0, the mean p=EiRzl=R,, and the variance 0’, it is straightforward to calculate EiMale,,0]}. Applying the same procedure, it is not difficult to evaluate the other term, E{Max[1%r-i 1-r)R,-K, 0]}. Then we can express the value of waiting. W. as a function of R,, given other parameter values. For a base- “ See Green (1993). pp. 691-3 for a treatment of the censored normal distribution. 88 case computation, we set the parameter values at r=0.05, q=0.2, r=0.3, 3:0. and K = 1. Figures 3.1 through 3.3 depict W for a range of R,. Figures 3.1 and 3.2 show three separate paths of W in response to changing values of the tax rate (r) and uncertainty (0') under the no-offset scheme. Figure 3.3 compares the paths of W between the no-loss-offset scheme and the full- loss-offset scheme for the base case.7 All three figures show that W is decreasing in R,. We can find the reason by examining the right-hand side of the expression (4) for W. Notice that all four terms are increasing in R,. Then W is decreasing in R,, if the difference between the last term and the first three terms enlarges as R, increases. The last term represents the sum of the current and the expected pre-tax cash flow from investing in the first period. The firm would lose this value by deferring the investment. Thus, W is downward sloping, because the value of the last term increases more rapidly than those of the first three terms as R, goes up. The figures also show that W is larger—that is, an immediate investment is discouraged—when the tax rate is higher, the uncertainty is greater, or there is no loss offset. This because NPV, in equation (2) and NPV, in equation (3) are affected differently by the changes in these parameter values. Let us first examine the tax effect. An increase in the tax rate reduces both NPV, and NPV,, since it reduces the firm's cash flow. 7 We have assumed no loss offset by setting s=0. On the contrary, we can assume full loss offset by setting s=oo. 89 T=0.3 Figure 3.1 - The Tax Rate It), the First-Period Revenue (R,). and the Value of Waiting (W) 90 In T T T T T T fr 1 fit I r- -( ). Cl )- ..I VI'I- "I 5 . II‘ - \ -. "' \ U=O.2 ‘ ro- \ ——o=O.3 ‘ k \ __ ~04 . I-\ \ - U—. a I. \ _ N- .. , I ‘—)— -' )- d h J I- .. O . “I T'- L 1 l 4 1 I 1 I l J l L 1 l 4 ‘1 00 01 02 03 04 0.5 06 07 08 09 10 Figure 3.2 - Uncertainty (0'), the First-Period Revenue (R,), and the Value of Waiting (W) 91 I”? T T T T T T f T T m I I “r )- -I F u: N )- .- \ full loss offset ~ \ — - no loss offset . I 1 1 1 1 1 I 1 1 1 1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0 R, Figure 3.3 - The Loss Offset, the First-Period Revenue (R,). and the Value of Waiting (W) 92 Recall that the firm that decides to wait has more flexibility than the firm that decides to invest now in optimizing the investment decision. Then the higher tax rate would have a smaller influence on the waiting firm than on the investing firm. This implies that the reduction in NPV, is less than the reduction in NPV,. and W becomes larger. However, the effect of a tax increase on W is minimal. On the other hand, uncertainty has a stronger effect on W than does the tax rate or the loss-offset scheme, under our plausible parameter values. In other words, the Jensen effect, or the effect of Jensen’s inequality from the convexity (concavity) of the value function, is greater than the effect of the tax rate or the loss-offset scheme. We can explain the importance of uncertainty in the context of irreversibility. When there is no irreversibility, we have no value of waiting, so we need only to focus on NPV,. Investigation of equation (2) shows that NPV, is concave, because the two subtracted terms, MaxIR,,0] and E{Max[R,,0]}}, are convex. This implies that uncertainty lowers NPV,. Therefore. if the investment is reversible, increased uncertainty lowers the firm value, and reduces the incentive to invest. This is the direct consequence of an option effect. In the presence of irreversibility, we should also consider NPV, that contains another option, namely, the option to invest in the second period. Since equation (3) for NPV, is convex, increased uncertainty raises NPV,. It follows that, because uncertainty increases NPV, and decreases NPV,. the value of waiting, W, which equals the difference between these two values, increases. This implies that, under irreversibility, growing uncertainty 93 further reduces an incentive to invest immediately. In a nutshell, uncertainty interacts with irreversibility to magnify the value of waiting. Our numerical solution confirms that this is exactly the case. There is another salient feature in the uncertainty effect. We can observe from Figure 3.2 that the effect of increasing uncertainty mitigates at a higher level of R,. In other words, the vertical distance between the curves shortens as R, increases. The reason is that the option effects become negligible, when R, rises to the sufficiently high levels. Recalling that R,=R,+e,, where e,~Ni0,o’). we can infer that, at a higher level of R,, R, is less likely to go down enough to be constrained by the options. In terms of NPV,, the government is less likely to get a chance of avoiding a tax refund. In terms of NPV,, the firm is less likely to get a chance of avoiding the down side loss. Likewise, both the government and the firm lose much of their benefits from flexibility at higher levels of R,. Then the effect of uncertainty on the value of the options dwindles, making the options worthless.“ A similar argument can be put forward by examining the effect of the loss-offset scheme in Figure 3.3. At lower values of R,, W is greater with no loss offset than with a full loss offset. As R, rises. however, the value of the options associated with the lack of a loss offset gradually declines. At a sufficiently high level of R,——in our case. in the vicinity of 0.4—there remains almost no effect solely from no loss offset, because it would be “ Statistically, this is equivalent to saying that the expected value of a lower censored random variable decreases. as the censoring region shrinks. 94 very unlikely that R, will go down below zero in the second period. It follows that the firm incurs an additional cost of investing, if the loss offset is not available, and the current profitability of the investment is low. This implies that the absence of loss offset may discriminate against infant firms or risky firms, because it is highly likely that these firms are in a low profit position eligible for a loss offset. The main message of our simple model is that a tax system is not neutral with respect to risk, and risky investments are discouraged without a loss offset. There are other studies as well that point out these possibilities. For example. in the model of Gordon (1985) cited above, there is no risk- sharing role of the government through income taxes under the no-loss- offset system. making the tax system biased against risky investments. Bulow and Summers (1984) articulate another possibility resulting from a flaw in the depreciation schemes. When the replacement cost of depreciable capital is fluctuating, the firm bears a capital risk. The firm may not be able to deduct this cost of risk, since depreciation deductions are predetermined against the original price of the assets. Then the tax system discourages an investment in the risky capital. These models are concerned with systematic risk that cannot be diversified away by a risk-averse firm. Since we assume a risk-neutral firm, the firm's risk attitude has no role to play, precluding the risk-sharing effect of taxes. Instead, our model highlights the option effects that discourage investment in the absence of a loss offset. The options affect the firm’s investment decision, regardless of the types of risk. The firm's tax liability is like selling an option to the government. This option has value, when 95 there is no loss offset. 0n the other hand. the firm has an option to invest under irreversibility. These two options work together to raise the value of waiting, and the cost of investing now. 3.3. Tax Asymmetries and Tax Claims: An Option Interpretation Tax systems in the U.S., as well as in other countries. are characterized by asymmetries in the tax structure. In many countries, firms' losses can be carried backward, or carried forward, in order to be written off against positive profits in other financial years. The refundability of the loss offset schemes, however, is far from perfect in many cases. It is common that the number of years over which the loss offset is applied is limited. Firms incur the interest costs during the carry-forward periods. It follows that firms investing in risky projects, or in their early years of operation, are likely to pay higher taxes. Asymmetries can also occur on the credit side. Firms are allowed to offset their taxes payable with the investment tax credit. But there are usually some caps on the amount of credit that is available.“ Firms are likewise treated differently, depending on whether they are subject to a credit limit. For the income levels under which the credit ceiling is binding, firms are, in fact, taxed at a lower marginal tax rate. since the tax credit is ° In the U.S., the investment tax credit was repealed by the 1986 tax reform. Until that time, the tax credit had been awarded with a ceiling. In 1981, a form of refundability was enacted. through 'Safe Harbor Leasing", to provide tax benefits for firms that could not fully use accelerated depreciation because of lack of sufficient tax liability. But this was repealed in 1982. 96 awarded as a fraction of taxes payable. Consider now a hypothetical asymmetric tax system. A firm pays income tax at rate r on its stochastic net operating income, R,. The firm is allowed a deprecation deduction, 0,, so long as the operating profit is sufficiently large to be deducted. We assume that D, is predetermined, while R, is contingent on the states of nature. The firm is also eligible for the investment tax credit at rate x, but the amount cannot exceed 1009 percent of the taxes payable.1o When the firm's taxable income, R,-D,. is negative, the tax authorities compensate the firm for its loss. The amount of tax refund is equal to a certain fraction, 17, of negative taxes payable. Hence. the degree of the loss offset depends on the value of n. Algebraically, the tax function is expressed as a composite maximum and minimum function of R,, TiR,) = Max[{riR,-D,)-Min[9riR,-D,), xKI}, at! 1-9) iR,-D,)]. (6) As the nested functional form implies, this function has two kinks. As illustrated in Figure 3.4, the kinks occur at R, (=D.) and R,(=xK/r6+D,), respectively. When R, is less than R, (region 1), the firm receives a refund equal to nrii-HliD,-R,). When R, is between R, and R,, (region 2), it pays taxes equal to ti 1-9liR,-D,l. ‘° We assume that the investment tax credit is allowed evenly throughout the lifetime of the firm. We can think of it as a credit being given against the interest cost on the investment expenditure, rK, in each time. Then its capitalization value Q is approximately equal to the initial cost of investment, K, because rKZ (l )t +r (=0 where r is the interest rate. This assumption is necessary in order to make the investment credit occur continuously for a firm that invests in a single stand-alone project. 3K, 97 Tax put in region 2 put in region 1 \ 0 R/ nr(l-9)(R-D) ,’ I 3'. ’ O. ’ I I I can in T(R'D)'KK region 2 .,.r(1-0)(R-D) Revenue (R,) call in region 3 region 1: R, < R, region 2: R, s R,