a u “a .- fir, 0. ”a“ a $2.. 4 Kuhwabmwfllm...» 2.: Iran. ‘ . I o .r :i “In“. «549.1. gaminfimmmwwx M :de WWW-Wu...» . ¢ . .h. (Hr, gum. “Wuhuhwn ‘ H.913...“ V “:7 ‘3.) .o , (a. 3.1163“ 40 v .v .t . :6 3.. uL, 4 u . a .3} 'l I»). 4 tray! 1... (131.. .8 It. fii Ii. .1 ‘ 314...}?! c e. nt.. 1715818 Michigan State Mdgigse 3600 University m» LIBRARY will? llllll‘llmm This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Induced Institutional Change in the Trade and Environment Debate: A Computable General Equilibium Application to NAFTA With Endogenous Regulation Setting presented by Heinz J. Jansen has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Agricultural Economics 4 Major professor Date 8/20/98 MSUis an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0- 12771 4 +_ fi_————- ————._-—fi__._~ .__ LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINE-3 return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE =4aiwm 1/” WM“ INDUCED INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE IN THE TRADE AND ENVIRONMENT DEBATE: A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPLICATION TO NAFTA WITH ENDOGENOUS REGULATION SETTING By Heinz J. Jansen A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fiilfillment of the requirements for the degree DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1998 A CON Bee; often Sim View ignor 'irminmon hbefaluanc application examined v influence 0 r{ignition i process dep of Ramos liberal mo, ABSTRACT INDUCED INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE IN THE TRADE AND ENVIRONMENT DEBATE: A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPLICATION TO NAFTA \VITH ENDOGENOUS REGULATION SETTING By Heinz J. Jansen Because of the assumption of constant emission factors, economy-environment models often show that free trade has negative environmental consequences. However, this pessimistic view ignores the possibility of trade strmgthening the demand for regulatory institutions. An "institutional optimism hypothesis", stating that the net environmental result of trade liberalization is benign, is thus formulated in this paper. The hypothesis can be understood as application of the “environmental Kuznets curve” to a trade context. The hypothesis is examined with a specially developed CGE model that allows decomposing the environmental influence of economic policies into growth effect, allocation effect, composition efl‘ect and regulation efl‘ect The latter is achieved by treating institutional change as an endogenous process dependent on income. Application of the CGE model to NAFTA, using a broad range of scenarios, supports the institutional optimism hypothesis. The net pollution efl'ect of trade liberalization is beneficial or insignificant, even for the country specializing in polluting industries. The implication is that in many cases environmental interests are served better by a focus on institution building in trading partners, than on the process of trade liberalization itself. The dissertation is organized in six chapters. Chapter 1 reviews the literature on trade and the environment; Chapter 2 develops the institutional optimism hypothesis in a simple theoretical model; Chapter 3 describes the CGE model designed to empirically examine the research question; Chapter 4 describes the model calibration; Chapter 5 presents the simulation results; and Chapter 6 concludes. Cop HEI Capyfisht by HEINZ J. JANSEN 1998 To Daniel iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS "Though I am suspicious of CGE models, I am very fond of CGE modelers. It must be that the process of model building and calibration leave in their wake a great deal of understanding about how real economies function”. (Edward E. Learner, 1993). The learning experience of writing this dissertation lasted substantially longer than I anticipated In particular, after I started my job at the European Commission four years ago, the completion of the dissertation was often a strain. Numerous people contributed in their own way to its completion. The longest-lasting encouragement comes from my parents who always inspired me to follow an academic path More than anyone, my parents wanted to see me complete my studies, thus providing the important impetus of giving me a bad conscience about procrastinating. I thank them for their love and support Undoubtedly, I owe most to my wonderful friend and wife Wanda who sufi‘ered with me all the way. Her love, patience, and encouragement made life in the all-but-dissertation limbo endurable; her proofreading skills helped to substantially speed-up and improve my writing; and finally she put things into perspective by giving birth to our son Daniel (sometime during the first draft of Chapter 4), whose broad smile makes this dissertation appear insignificant. I am grateful to my boss and friend, Manfred Bergmann, for holding my back free so that I could finally move this paper to completion fi'om its everlasting near-finished status. Academically, I am indebted to the members of my dissertation committee: Charley Ballard, Sandra Batie, John Hoehn and Tom Reardon. Ted Tomasi provided guidance and financial assistance, before his departure from Michigan State University. My committee members made the long-distance completion of this paper as smooth as possible, and willingly accepted printing out hundreds of pages sent to them by email. All provided thoughtful critical comments. I am especially indebted to Charley who guided me though the long process of completing the CGE model. Finally, I owe my gratitude to Tom for being my committee chair who guided me wisely and swiftly through the final stages of the process. TABLE Oi TABLE OI CHAPTER 1.]. lntrodu 1.2. Posmor 1.3. Key Cc 1.3.1. Ta 1.3.2. En 1.4. Tradinc 1.4.1. En 1.4.2 Fa: 1.4.3. En 1.4 4. P0] 14.5. Err. 1.5. Poverty 1.5.1. Cor 1.5.2. Em 1.6 Regard 16.1. C0: 1.6.3. Em Climax: 2.1.1. De. TABLE OF CONTENTS TABLE OF FIGURES TABLE OF TABLES CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION AND LITERATURE REVIEW 1.1. Introduction 1.2. Position of this Dissertation within the Trade and Environment Literature 1.3. Key Concepts for Understanding the Trade and Environment Interaction 1.3.1. Taxonomy of Trade Effects Influencing the Environment 1.3.2. Environmental Endowment 1.4. Traditional Pessimism Hypothesis of Trade and Environment 1.4.1. Environment and Comparative Advantage 1.4.2. Factor Mobility and the Industrial Flight Hypothesis 1.4.3. Empirical Findings on Industrial Flight Hypothesis 1.4.4. Pollution Haven Hypothesis 1.4.5. Empirical Evidence of the Pollution Haven Hypothesis 1.5. Poverty Attraction Hypothesis 1.5.1. Conditions for the Hypothesis 1.5.2. Empirical Findings on Poverty Attraction Hypothesis 1.6. Research Gaps and Purpose of this Paper 1.6.1. Contribution to Empirical Research 1.6.2. Inclusion of Environmental Extemality 1.6.3. Endogenous Treatment of Pollution Factors CHAPTER 2 THE INSTITUTIONAL OPTIMISM HYPOTHESIS 2.1. Economic Development as Explanation of Environmental Stringency 2.1.1. Development and Production Patterns 2.1.2. Development and Institutions 2.1.3. Trade and Environmental Regulation 2.2 Trade Model with Endogenous Environmental Regulation 2.2.1. The Standard Model 2.2.2. The Modified Model 2.3. The Institutional Optimism Hypothesis 2.3.1. Formulation of the Hypothesis 2.3.2. Empirical Evidence 2.4. An Illustrative Application of the Institutional Optimism Hypothesis: A decomposition procedure 2.4.1. Introduction and Case Description 2.4.2. Decomposition with Constant Regulation Level 2.4.3. Decomposition with Endogenous regulation level 2.5. Preliminary Conclusions CHAPTER 3 MODELING TRADE AND ENVIRONIVIENT IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM FRAMEWORK 3.1. Empm 31.1. E. 3.1.2. C. 31.3 $1 3.2. NorrT 3.2.1.0 3.2215: 3.3. Model 3.3.1. Pl 3.3.2. 11 3.3.3.11 3.3.4. L 33.5. T 3.3.6. I 3.3.7. C CH‘LPTEF 4.1 Styltze 4.1.1. 8 4.1.2. A 4.1.3.13 4.1.4. T 4.1.5. E 4.2. Ennrc 42.1. S 4.2.2. 8 4.2.3. A 42.4. E 4.2.5. ( 4.2.6. I? 4.2.7. } 4.2.8. 2 4.2.9.\ 4.2.10, “Wm 3.1. Empirical Modeling Approaches 3.1.1. Econometric Approaches 3.1.2. Case Studies 3.1.3. Simulation Approaches 3.2. Non-Technical Model Description 3.2.1. Overview 3.2.2 Economy-Environment Nexus in the Model 3.3. Model Equations: Technical Specification 3.3.1. Production 3.3.2. Households 3.3.3. Regulation Setting and Supply of Productive and Abatement Capital 3.3.4. Labor Supply 3.3.5. Trade 3.3.6. Taxes and Government 3.3.7. Closure CHAPTER 4 DATA DESCRIPTION AND MODEL CALIBRATION 4.1 Stylized facts of the North American Free Trade Area 4.1.1. Social Accounting Matrix 4.1.2. Asymmetric Structure of NAFTA 4.1.3. Difi'erences in Economic Development of NAFTA States 4.1.4. Trade Protection before NAFTA 4.1.5. Elasticities 4.2. Environmental Components 4.2.1. Sectoral Emission Coefiicients in the United States 4.2.2. Sectoral Abatement Costs in the United States 4.2.3. Abatement Functions 4.2.4. Extension of Environmental Relationships to Canada and Mexico 4.2.5. Calculation of Total Emissions 4.2.6. Relationship of Total Emissions to Air Quality 4.2.7. Health Effect of Air Quality 4.2.8. Effect of Health on Labor Productivity 4.2.9. Welfare Efi‘ect of Pollution 4.2.10. Political Income Elasticity for Pollution Abatement CHAPTER 5 SIMULATION RESULTS 5.1. Building up the Model Structure of the Central Case 5.1.1. Simple Trade Scenario with Internationally Immobile Capital 5.1.2. Introducing the Extemality 5.1.3. Introducing the Regulation Efi'ect 5.2. Introducing Factor Mobility 5.3. Importance of the Oil Sector 5.3.1. Leaving out the Emission Efi‘ect 5.3.2. Exclusion of Mexican Oil Sector from NAFTA 5.4. Sensitivity to Calibration Parameters 5.4.1. Using a toxicity weighted emission factor 5.4.2. Various Pollution Indicators 5.4.3. Abatement Elasticity 83 84 87 101 107 107 110 114 116 117 119 121 123 123 123 126 127 137 141 143 144 147 152 155 158 158 160 161 162 162 164 164 164 174 176 178 183 183 184 186 186 187 188 5.4.4. Abatement Function 5.4.5. Labor Supply Elasticity 5.4.6. Demand Elasticities 5.4.7. Elasticity of Scale 5.4.8. Revenue Recycling 5.5. Variations of the Regulation Equation 5.5.1. Various Regulation Elasticities 5.5.2. Policy Function Connected to Wages 5.5.3. Quantitative Restrictions 5.6. Unilateral Actions 5.6.1. Unilateral Changes in Abatement Intensity 5.6.2. Sectorally Optimal Regulation 5.6.3. Some Considerations on the Optimal Emissions Level 5.7. Tentative Conclusions CHAPTER 6 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 6.1. Research Question 6.1.1. Introduction 6.1.2. Literature Review. Traditional Pessimism 6.1.3. The Envirornmental Kuznets Curve 6.1.4. Decomposition of Pollution 6.1.5. Institutional Optimism Hypothesis 6.2. Model Description and Calibration 6.2.1. Social Accounting Matrix 6.2.2. Production 6.2.3. Households 6.2.4. Government 6.2.5. Trade 6.2.6. Emissions and Abatement 6.2.7. Extemality 6.2.8. Institutions 6.3. Polity Scenarios and Baseline 6.3.1. Policy Scenarios 6.3.2. Dependence of Results on Pre-NAFT A Trade Barriers 6.4 Macroeconomic Effects of Policy Scenarios 6.4.1. Scenario 1: Full Trade Liberalization with Immobile Capital 6.4.2. Scenario 2: Full Trade Liberalization with Mobile Capital 6.4.3. Scenario 3: Leaving out the Petroleum Sector 6.4.4. Scenario 4: Unilateral Increase irn Environmental Stringency 6.5 Environmental Efl‘ects of Policy Scenarios 6.5.1. Scenario 1: Full Trade Liberalization with Irnmobile Capital 6.5.2. Scenario 2: Full Trade Liberalization with Mobile Capital 6.5.3. Scenario 3: Leaving out the Petroleum Sector 6.5.4. Scenario 4: Unilateral Increase in Environmental Stringency 6.6. Conclusions 1 89 190 192 194 I94 194 194 198 199 201 201 205 206 208 214 214 214 215 217 218 220 222 223 223 224 224 224 225 226 227 228 228 229 23 1 23 l 232 233 233 235 235 237 238 239 240 APPENDIX: CALCULATION ON OPTIMAL REGULATION-NCOME ELASTICITY 254 viii Figure M. De Figure 2-2. Ira Figure 2-3: Ira Figure 2-4. Em Figure 3-2. Figure 5-1: Cor regu Figure 5.2: The elast Figure 5.3. The (pen Figure H De TABLE OF FIGURES Figure 2-1. Decomposition of the environmental Kuznets curve 52 Figure 2-2. Trade liberalization with constant environmental regulations 68 Figure 2-3: Trade liberalization with endogenous environmental regulation setting 71 Figure 24. Environmental effect of trade liberalization: Decomposition into scale, allocation and composition efi‘ect 79 Figure 3-1. Structure of the production function in ETERNA 100 Figure 3-2. Economy and Environment Interaction in ETERNA 102 Fignn'e 5-1: Contribution of Individual Sectors to Overall Emission Changes (igrnoring regulation effect) 172 Figure 5.2: The impact of various levels of regulation elasticity on GDP and welfare (Zero elasticity case set to 1) 196 Figure 5.3. The impact of regulation elasticity on total pollutiorn, growth and composition efi‘ect (percentage changes fiom pre NAFTA base case) 197 Figure 6-1. Decomposition of Pollution Causation 218 Table 2-1: 5 Table 3-1. ( 11 Table 5-1. 11 e Table 5.2. S c Table 53. I Table 5-4. 1 (1 Table 5.5. C Table 56 C Table 5-7. S in Table 5-8 In Table 59. E Table S-lO. . .\ Table 5-1 1. . Table 5.12. .' Table 5-13_ 1 Table 5-14. I Table 5-16. Table 5-17. 1 Table 5-18. 1 Table 5-19. 1 Table 5-20. I Table 521. 1 Table 5.21 4 TABLE OF TABLES Table 2-1: Summary of model results Table 3-1. Comparison of different empirical approaches to assess trade and environment interactions Table 5-1. Macroecononnic efl‘ects of trade liberalization (immobile capital; no extemalities) Table 5-2. Sectoral calculation of ennissions impact of trade liberalization (immobile capital; no extemalities) Table 5-3. Emissions impact of trade liberalization (immobile capital; no extemalities) Table 5-4. Trade Liberalization when Extemalities are included: Welfare Change (irrnrnobile capital) Table 5-5. Central case simulation with immobile capital Table 5-6. Central case simulation with mobile capital Table 5-7. Sectoral calculation of emissions impact of trade liberalization (mobile capital; no extemalities) Table 5-8. Influence of the petrol sector on the overall emissions impact Table 5-9. Exclusion of Mexican petroleum sector from NAFTA Table 5-10. Replacing TSP in base case (immobile capital) with toxicity weights: Macroecornonnic impact Table 5-11. Comparison of the Composition effect for various pollutants Table 5-12. Sirnulatiorns with a low abatement elasticity Table 5-13. Central case with labor supply elasticity of zero Table 5-14. Central case with infinite labor supply elasticity Table 5-16. Regulation efl‘ect as function of wages Table 5-17. Definition of restriction target in quantities of each sector Table 5-18. Unilateral reduction in unit emissions by one third in the United States Table 5-19. Unilateral reduction in unit emissions by one third in Mexico Table 5-20. Unilateral reduction in unit emissions by one third in Canada Table 5-21. Optimal sectoral regulation level Table 5-22. Analysis of different factors on their influence on modeling results 72 95 166 170 173 175 177 179 182 184 185 187 188 189 191 192 198 199 202 204 204 205 211 1.1. Tntrodu The in sharp rise in pollution Se that trade m Notably, the 10 study trat Study group Problem em FIQ Trade CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION AND LITERATURE REVIEW 1.1. Introduction The increasing globalization of the world’s econorrnies has resulted in recent years in a sharp rise in interest in the interaction between intemational trade, environmental quality and pollution Several international bodies have reacted to the political pressure and the recogrnition that trade might have a negative impact on the environmental situation in various countries. Notably, the newly established World Trade Organization (WT O) has established a committee to study trade and environment issues. Similarly, tlne creep and tlne UNC'TAD have set up study groups to review the relationship between trade and environment. Rarely has this problem entered the political debate more forcefnnlly than in the context of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). NAFTA brought to the forefront of discussion the environmental efi‘ects of trade due to unequal economic development and regulatory standards of the nations involved. The opening of borders was feared to turn the Mexico into a pollution haven dnat erodes American environmental standards. The number of articles published in the last few years on the environmental aspects of NAFTA, or on trade and environment in general, certainly goes into the hundreds. It will therefore be dificult to provide any substantive new argument to the debate that has not been made somewhere. Despite the richness in argumentative material, however, there is a surprising lack of quantitative information on the various factors that shape the environment and trade interaction. This nnissing information on the relative importance of the economy- environment interactions is matched by a lack of coherence in the tlneoretical conclusions on what to expect when trade barriers are removed. literature art the poverty pan. the in: with the m 513165 that c The poem adnantagc 115130111855 This paper will advance the discussion in several ways. A first contribution will be to sort the mechanisms and arguments. Other authors have provided literature reviews before. Here the approach will have the sole focus of what happens when countries witln difl‘erent environmental standards engage in trade. This approach allows the organization of the existing literature around two empirically testable hypotheses: the traditional pessimism hypothesis and the poverty attraction hypothesis. The traditional pessimism hypothesis has two parts. Its first part, the industrial flight hypothesis, predicts that polluting industries end up in the countries with the most lax environmental regulation. Its second part, the pollution haven hypothesis, states that countries use this mecharnism to relax environmental standards to attract industries. The poverty attraction hypothesis states that underdeveloped countries have a comparative advantage in polluting industries, which they cannot strictly regulate. Under these two hypotheses trade would likely to be bad for the environment. The second contribution of this paper is the formulation of a counter hypothesis to the poverty attraction hypothesis, which we call the institutional optimism hypothesis. Its starting poirnt in contrast to the other two hypotheses is that the regulation stringency of a country cannot be treated as a cereris paribus condition. By making poor countries wealthier, trade contributes to increasing the countries’ capacity and willingness to improve its environment This tendency will in many cases outweigh the effect of any shift in the location of polluting industry. This hypothesis will be illustrated in a simple theoretical model. The third contribution of this paper is the empirical test of all three hypotheses in a computable general equilibrium model of the North American Free Trade Agreement. The interest of this paper goes beyond that of the narrow goal of only analyzing the trade- environment relationship of the NAFTA. Due to the large difl‘erences in the econonnic deneloprr of .NAFT case stud probably '1 ofsuchur mahze tr; modek ha bOth nece: milmnmer m 51mm.- development between the USA and Canada on the one side and Mexico on the other, the case of NAFTA can also be seen as a rrnicrocosm of the forces at work in North/South trade liberalization in general. Therefore, the present paper understands the analysis of NAFTA as a case study of a nnore general phenomenon, where it takes advantage of the fact that this case is probably better documented than any other case of trade liberalization between trading partners of such nmequal development levels. The computable general equilibrium (CGE) tool, which is developed in this paper to analyze trade and environment interactions, incorporates a number of components that other models have neglected. In particular, (i) it fully incorporates a pollution extemality, which is both necessary to gain a correct welfare assessment and the production feedback of environmental policy. (ii) It is a three country model, which allows testing as to whether there are systematic difi‘erences between Nortlnem and Southern countries, to test the poverty attraction hypothesis. (iii) It treats the regulation levels as endogenous. This feature allows the analysis of the irnstitutional optirrnism hypothesis. (iv) It provides a full disaggregation of the various efi‘ects of trade on the environment. Other authors focus on aggegate numbers which tend to give faulty impressions. The empirical results show that (at least for local pollutants), the net result of trade liberalization is an environmental improvement. Therefore, in general, trade is good for the environment, even where large regulatory differences exist. The remainder of this introductory chapter further motivate the arguments just sketched To tlnis end it will first position the empirical questions with the remainder of the trade and environment literature. It will tlnen briefly discuss some methodological prelinninaries. After this itwillgoon to undocpoveru Chapter simple theore‘ analysis of in equilibrium rt 561 and mint 01413131 6 pr: 1.2. Position The pi Watch a: 15 The quest] it will go on to discussing the theoretical and empirical literature on the traditional pessirnnism and fine poverty attraction hypothesis. Chapter 2 formulates the institutional optimism hypothesis. This idea is developed in a simple theoretical model that incorporates an endogenous policy formation process into fine arnalysis of trade-environment relationships. The system of equations hr the computable general equilibrium model for the empirical testing is shown in Chapter 3. Chapter 4 describes the data set and calibration of the model to NAFTA. Chapter 5 presents various simulation runs. Chapter 6 provides a summary and concluding remarks. 1.2. Position of this Dissertation within the Trade and Environment Literature The present paper focuses on assessing the econorrnic interactions between environmental regulation and the pattern of trade. The issue can be divided into two sub-problems. First, finere is the question of what effect a given differential in environmental stringency has on the trade specialization of countries. This effect will be important in deterrnirning the degree to which trade liberalization results in an improvement or a deterioration of the environmental situatiorn of the afi‘ected countries. The following chapter will provide an overview over fine aburndant fineoretical literature and fine more scarce empirical literature on finis aspect. Second, trade liberalization directly and (mostly) indirectly influences fine level of regulatory stringency of conmtries, as it shapes bofin fine economy and society of a country. Chapter 2 will attempt to shed some light on this issue and develop a simple but irnstructive model finat shows finat fine internalization of the regulatory standards can fundamentally alter fine findings of standard models. The twin questions of how trade influences fine environment and how regulation influencestradedoesnotexhaustfineliteraturefinatcanbefoundurnderfine“tradearnd environment” label. At least five furfiner topics exist, which will not be addressed in finis paper. 1W Probably fine most important driver of fine environmental component of fine NAFTA debate was fine emotional and political argument finat fiee trade erodes fine national sovereignty irn setting environmental standards (Shrybman 1990)‘. Hostility against fiee trade was focused especially finrough fine notorious tuna-dolphin case. The United States imposed an embargo against fine import of Mexican tuna fish caught wifin purse-seine nets, which kill dolphins irn a greater number finan US. law permits (Audley 1993,). The GATT (General Agreement on Tarifl‘s arnd Trade) Dispute Settlement Panel ruled firat fine import ban violated fine irnternatiornal trade code on grounds finat regulating fine production process of a good falls nrrnder fine jurisdiction of fine producing country only.2 The importing country has no right to impose its particular environmental preferences for production processes on anofiner courntry (Arden- Clarke 1992b). The Standards Code of fine GATT does, however, allow a country to impose import restrictions on goods which do not meet national product standards, such as certain chemicals, pharmaceuticals, and wastes. On a multilateral level, examples of finis kind are fine lInthisrconterlrt, ithas beenproposcdtousefineterrn "deregulatedtrade" overthemore enotionally positive expression ”free trade” (Daly 1993). 2 The panel has a point in stating that environmental restrictions should nn principle not be treated difierenfiy from difi‘erences nn labor and capital use among countries. However, it evidenfiy did not take into consideration finat both Mexican and U. S. comparnies fish in the same body of water, ratherthanwithintheirnational waters. Because everytunafishharvestedby Mexicansennno longer be fished by American fishers, the case should have been treated like a transboundary extenality. Basel Con Contentio (CUESXS In 11 Political p allow for l An ovum; m hm Pacify em a US. com Free Trade Whil Particular i, have alrea¢ cmcmtfate Basel Convention on fine Control of Trans-boundary Movements of Hazardous Wastes and fine Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora (ClTESXStevens 1993, GATT 1992). In light of finese concenns, amendments to fine original NAFTA treaty have been made. Political pressure led to an inclusion of side agreements about environmental standards finat allow for heavy fines and even possible trade sanctions, if national trade laws are not enforced An overview of fine agreements is provided by Hufoauer and Schott (1993, p. 1590. There exists, however, some agreement finat fine NAFTA side agreements are desigrned mainly to pacify environmental interests, wifin limited practical implications (Audley 1993). Additionally, a US. court ordered to undertake an "Environmental Impact Statement" of fine Norfin American Free Trade Agreement (Wall Street Journal, 1 July 1993; Hufbauer and Schott 1993, p.159). While fine efinical considerations of trade liberalization certairnly merit attention, in particular insofar as finey affect countries wifin substantially difi‘ering pollution standards, finey have already been spelled out in ofiner places (e.g., Bhagwati 1993, Daly 1993). This paper will concentrate on fine narrower economic issues involved. 223 a. 2 m .5 nm- ' u ' WC - Vi onmen.:. uoehavir' H v.0 __. 11'; Related to fine first issue, finere exists a link between trade and environment in fine political sense firat it has been proposed to use trade sanctions as a means of pushing countries wifin lax environmental regulations into complying wifin stricter standards (Anderson 1995). The link between trade and fine environment can be seen as analogous to finat between trade and human rights issues. There is no pretext of a causality. Trade policy (such as fine refusal to grant most favored nation status) is used only for want of a better leverage point on fine achievement of a policy goal. This political aspect will also be neglected in fine present paper. t:- ‘4 D) L Of a d ssurt that u For several 1 venom sche UNClAD 1 (produced I “Went exert a can the “T0 tr: Pmduct in c border tax a “Winner 4-1-.1- H 5 l’ = ardinintem ' a .r it a -* ' 0'1. " 2:. amen- Of a difi‘erent nature and more focused on environmental issues are questions of how to assure finat unilateral or international environmental policies are not undermined finrough trade. For several tools, fineoretical research and practical applications can be found. First, finere are various schemes to introduce environmental labelling (e.g., Jha, Vossenenaar, and Zarilli 1993; UNCT AD 1995, OECD 1997a). This approach means that environmentally fiiendly products (produced at home and abroad) can obtain a label finat informs consumers about fine environmental standards applied in its production process. These cornsumer awareness schemes exert a certain pressure on producers to apply clean technologies. Second, in accordance wifin fine WTO treaty, signatories to international environmental agreements can limit trade on fine product in question (OECD 1997b). Third, finere exists a (mostly fineoretical) literature on border tax adjustments, i.e. a compensation bofin for imports and exports for difi‘erences in environmental taxes. (Mani 1996, Scherp and Suardi 1997). 4 T ' e There exists a broad array of literature on trade wifin hazardous products (see for instance: Hackrnann 1994; Kummer 1994). While finis is an interesting ecornonnic topic in its own right, fine present paper focuses on fine influence of environmental regulation on fine broad economy, not on a narrow set of individual products. In practice, finis exclusiorn means finat pollution is only considered insofar as it afi‘ects fine production process of finose goods first are ofinerwise not considered harmful. The trade in hazardous waste is finerefore ignored. 5Di of tim liiinan nm Game fineory is one of fine most fruitful areas of fineoretical research in fine field of trade and environment. There exist numerous models looking at fine policy outcome when fine trade 7 and mum commas. global), m (perfect cc more), etc interactive models. A this heat. literature u L3.Kgy( and environmental policy irn one country is not seen as independent from fine policies of other countries. Variations of finese models include fine type of extemality (local, cross-horde, global), market structures (monopoly, oligopoly, duopoly, atomistic), types of belnaviour (perfect competition, Nash, Bertrand competition), fine number of countries involved (two or nnore), etc. However, very few papers of finis type attempt any quantification of finese interactive aspects. At best, finey tend to be limited to numerical examples of fineir fineoretical models. As our focus is more of an applied nature, rafiner finan one of (optimal) policy design, finis literature is also largely ignored. As it would be difiicult to provide a brief review of fine literature in fine field, the reader is referred to Ulph (1994). 1.3. Key Concepts for Understanding the Trade and Environment Interaction The task of reviewing fine literature is facilitated through fine fact finat fine dispute between proponents and opponents of free trade, in light of differing environmental regulations, is not a dispute over mefinodological issues. Bofin sides use similar economic models and largely agree on fine relevant mechanism finat trade liberalization will induce. The starting point is finat trade will change fine structure of the economy. Some sectors will suffer under fine burden of new competition, some industries will relocate into fine country finat gives finem a competitive advantage. Labor-intensive irndustnies might have an incentive to relocate to fine country wifin lower wage rates (in finis case, Mexico). This could be because of lax environmental regulations or ofiner factors, such as low labor cost. Other sectors will benefit fiom fine enlarged markets. Others may resettle, because finey seek lax environmental regulations. On fine ofiner hand, some it mauve : able to buy rr an economic magnitudes . cmsequent s Todrs following tax 1.3.1. Tuon Gtossr hand, some industries in fine wealfinier country (United States3) will expand because finey have a comparative advantage over fineir Mexican counterparts, or simply because a richer Mexico is able to buy nnore products fiom fine US. The dispute about what fine net efi‘ect of finese changes on economic welfare and fine environment are, lies in different beliefs about fine respective magnitudes of fine likely changes (as well as in differences in fine willingness to accept consequent sectoral and regional redistribution of economic activities). To disentangle fine various efi‘ects of trade liberalization on fine environment, fine followirng taxonomy is useful: 1.3.1. Taxonomy of Trade Effects Influencing the Environment Grossman and Krueger (1995) have disaggregated fine economic changes finat afl‘ect fine environmental quality into finree components, fine scale effect, fine composition effect, and fine technique efi‘ect.4 Salim If trade increases fine size of an economy wifinout changing anyfining else, fine resource use and pollution level will increase by fine same proportion. The intuition behind fine scale efi'ect is simple. If, for example, twice as many vehicles drive on fine roads, fossil finel emission will double, too. If trade finerefore increases fine national income, ceterr’s paribus fine efi‘ect on fine environment is deleterious. 3 Because of the relatively minor role of the Canada-Mexico interaction and the relative similarity between the Canadian and United States economy, the following discussion treats NAFTA as a bilateral treaty between Mexico and fine US. In general, the arguments concenning the situation of the United States are equally valid for Canada. " Compare also Stevens (1993). gm mmpositlm benefits of f.- the contracti the composi scale effect ._g 2 about output i‘OWCVBI, als World Dcve] W The conclusion of fine previous paragraph is only valid if fine composition of fine economy does not change. Wifinin fine economy, fine distributiorn of costs and benefits of free trade is uneven. If fine expanding sectors are relatively pollution-intensive while fine contracting ones are non-polluting, fine scale effect will be reinforced. In fine reverse case, fine composition efi‘ect works to reduce fine pollution level, and may potentially outweigh fine scale efl‘ect. W The composition efi’ect again provides additional information only about output changes of fine economy. Change in fine environmental intensity of production can, however, also be fine result of changing techniques used in fine production processes. The World Development Report 1992 (World Bank 1992, p. 39) decomposes fine technique efi‘ect furfiner into two components. First, an increase in fine input-output efficiency reduces fine demand for resource inputs. Secondly, polluting inputs can be substituted wifin nnore environmentally benign inputs. Modifications in fine production technique are fine finird important linkage finrough which trade can change fine quality of fine environment Of fine finree efi‘ects, finis technique effect is fine least understood, and fine most difiicult to model analytically. Beyond fine assertion of certain elasticities of substitution between factor inputs as prices change, economic fineory still does a poor job of explaining what induces techrnical change. In altering fine scale, fine composition, or fine production techrnique of an economy, trade policy is environmentally relevant. The pafinways finrough which finese alterations takes place are many, and usually concern more finan one of finese finree effects. Fundamentally, fine dispute between proponents and opponents of trade liberalization lies in difi‘erent beliefs about fire respective magnitudes of fine likely changes, as well as in differences in fine willingness to accept fine consequent sectoral and regional redistribution of economic activities and fineir 10 mrmmcrnral the efi'em imn throng the en through empn scopeofanan environmental consequences. Because finere is a lack of studies finat quantify fine magnitude of fine efi‘ects involved, positions in fine discussion are based largely on faifin, a rifi finat goes right finrough fine envirornmental movement itself. While fine issue can (at least in principle) be settled finrough empirical analysis, emotional issues accompany finese disputes and go beyond fine scope of a narrow economic analysis. 1.3.2. Environmental Endowment As a second preliminary, it is necessary to define fine economic concept of "endowment" as it is used in fine following review of fine trade literature. The literal interpretation of fine term would simply mean fine number of units of a given factor finat is available to fine economy at fine beginning of fine analysis. For fine purposes of fine trade literature, fine term needs to be interpreted more loosely in two important aspects. First, endowment is an aggegation of sub- urnits of difi‘erent qualities. Wifinout actually bofinering about fire fineoretical complexities involved in fine economic aggregation, it should be understood finat fine concept denotes simply a vague descriptiorn of relative availability of a certain class of input factors. Second, practically no factor is really fixed in its supply. Given fine right incentives, fine availability of any factor- for production purposes- can be increased. People can change fine amount finey work, plow more land, and so forfin. Natural endowment in fine way it is used here is finerefore not identical wifin fine natural assirnilative capacity, i.e., fine ability of fine environment to absorb pollutants or to provide raw materials for production. Availability of resources for production results from fine interactiorns of demand for assirnilative services, and from fine public preferences and irnstitutional settings finat make finem accessible (Blackhurst 1977). ll don‘t worl Ofcollaps: Bed in pn caning“ The concept of environmental endowment and of fine pollution-intensity of a good are amorphous, as production may affect a wide number of envirornmental media to a varying mt They should be understood here in the broad fineoretical sense of general availability and use of fine environmental medium (Leonard 1988). The treatment of environment irn economic nnodeling can be as understood analogous to finat of labor, which is also fine aggregatiorn connponents finat difi‘er in qualities like skills and training. The absorptive capacity of fine environment is only fine ceiling to fine use of environmental inputs. This limit is usually only reached under duress, in fine same way finat people usually don't work all hours finey are awake. In bofin cases, fine ceiling can be exceeded only at fine cost of collapse, and is efi‘ectively binding.5 The usual amount of bofin labor and environment finat is used inn production falls below finis fineoretical extreme, and people keep leisure time as well as certain environmental factors out of production. The availability of environment is fine result of economically and institutiornally determined artificial scarcity and demand for assinnilative services finat result fionn consumption, production, and technology. Environmental availability is similar to fine supply of labor, which is not simply a linear function of fine population, but depends on wage rates, irndividual preferences, and cultural and structural idiosyncrasies of countries finat may keep certain groups like women and minorities from working, or may force some to work against fineir wills. ’Undcrextrenecircumstances,theymaybeexceeded overashortperiod oftinne, but in botheases their future production potential will be reduced. 12 milabilitjr neural ph) economy 1 denote the quantity in resource at States, be magnitude Nuke-st US. has, 1 lighter env The Infinesamewayfinatchangesinwagescanalterfinesupplyoflaborinaneconomy,fine availability of environment also varies wifin changes in fine opportunity cost of resources. The actual physical availability of environment is finerefore relevant for fine compositiorn of fine ecornonny and fine determination of trade pattenns only irnsofar as it influences fine political and institutional availability of environment for fine production process. Factor endowment does not denote fine maximum fineoretical level of availability of environment or labor-capital, but fine quantity used in equilibrium. It is in finis sense finat Mexico, for instance, could be called resource abundant, because it is relatively cheaper and easier to pollute here finan in fine Urnited States, because regulations and enforcement are relatively lax. If one looks ornly at fine magnitude of resources per capita, one would come to fine opposite conclusion finat Mexico is resource—scarce compared wifin fine United States. Relative environmental abundance in fine US. has, however, been tunned into relative scarcity, finrough fine force of fine law filat sets tighter environmental standards for American producers finan finose fineir Mexican counterparts face. There exist a variety of mechanisms finrough which fine supply of environmental resources may be restricted. This restriction could be achieved finrough regulatory instrummts finat are enforced by fine government, or finrough a sale of fine rights to exploit fine resources, eifirer fiom private owners or a state agency. The same level of environmental quality can be attained using eifiner quality standards or monetary instruments such as taxes or emission permits. As most of fine models in fine following discussion abstract from transactions costs and pay no attention to fine distributional consequences of different regulations, no distinction- of fine type of instruments is necessary. The implicit price of regulatory instruments could be translated into fine explicit price finat results from a limitation of fine endowment finrougln l3 emissm perm market value 0: nreouroe as ir sl incremental ; In the fol measure that c with the letter 0; not enforced in ”Mg pm 0056, of entire cUltstralm is not ‘9831 Wills. My. Such as it hunting the use mm a re “WWI Uri Worms] 5 0051:. emission permits issued by fine state. It is finerefore easiest to understand price as fine explicit market value of finese tradable permits to avoid fine complex rhetoric of interpreting fine price of a resource as its shadow productivity (i.e., the increased output finat would have resulted fiom an incremental increase in its use). In fine following discussion, environmental regulation is to be understood only as finose measures finat enterprises actually have to undertake. This requirement need not be identical wifin fine letter of fine law. Many countries have very strict regulations on fine books which are not enforced irn practice, eifiner finrough corruptiorn, lack of enforcement tools, or a political bargaining process. National or local governments may grant exemptions from, or carry fine costs, of envirorunental regulations in order to attract irnvestrnents, so fine environmental cornstraint is not binding finat for fine firms. In ofiner cases, fine de facto constraints may exceed legal constraints, as social pressures can block certain types of investment finat are perceived as risky, such as waste dumps and power plants (Leonard 1988, 65). Whatever is fine cause of limiting fine use of environmental functions for fine economic process, for fine following discussiorn, a restricted availability is interpreted as economically equivalent to a limited endowment Unless explicitly stated, fine discussion will also neglect any reductiorn in envirornmental extemalities. This means finat environmental policies always imply increase costs. 14 1.4. Tradiri otpressnon predictien 0 there are us in an ecornor n the theo relemt inn one or two Swim we findings. 1.4. Traditional Pessimism Hypothesis of Trade and Environment The complexity of fine interactions between trade and fine environment finds is expressiorn in a cornsiderable and rapidly growing body of literature‘. An exact theoretical prediction of fine net efi‘ect of trade liberalization on fine level of pollution is dificult, because finere are usually a number of counteracting mechanisms at work Since fine level of complexity irn an economic analysis rises rapidly wifin fine inclusion of additional elemens, finere is no work in fine fineoretical literature on trade and fine environment finat attemps to incorporate all relevant interactions between fine environment and fine economy. Rafiner, most papers focus on one or two important aspecs finat could be brought forward by a trade liberalization. In a late section we will report on what empirical literature finere is to corroborate fine fineoretical findings. 1.4.1. Environment and Comparative Advantage The simplest modelling approach in fine literature is based on fine classical Heckscher- 0hlin model with two countries, two goods, and two factors. Environment simply serves as one input factor while fine ofiner factor is a composite good, consisting of labor and capital (Ohlirn 193 5). Under a number of special conditions (perfect competitiorn, zero transportation coss, incomplete specialization, identical linearly homogenous production furnctions, identical homofinetic preferences, absence of external econorrnies, constant relative factor intensities at all relative factor prices, factors homogeneous in quality, and fine number of factors no greater finarn the number of commodities), fine finree basic fineorems of international trade can be derived ‘ An earlier review ofthe literature has been undertaken by Dean (1992). 15 The firs output and in trade) output of the input f: that is recur: compared wl country Whel marginal pr0< As trac countries. 1h ”imitations, lmnobile be The first is fine factor price equalization fineorem. It states fine basic interaction between output arnd input prices irn an open economy. In a situation of autarky (i.e., in fine absence of trade) output prices in fine two countries will generally difi‘er, reflecting fine difl‘erent scarcifies of fine input factors. In a country finat is relatively abundant in environmental resources, a good finat is resource—intensive will be relatively cheaper finan in a country where resources are scarce compared wifin labor and capital. Similarly fine input factors will be nnore expensive in a country where finey are scarce finan where finey are abundant, reflecting fineir decreasing marginal productivity. As trade barriers are removed, fine prices of fine traded goods are equalized across fine countries. The factor price equalization fineorem now states finat, under fine above listed set of assumptions, fine factor prices will also be equal in fine two countries, even when fine factors are immobile between filem. Factor prices are a function of output prices only. Wifin finis equalization of bofin output and input prices established, fine standard result of trade fineory follows automatically: A country exports goods finat are intensive in fine use of fine factor wifin which fine country is well endowed A resource-abundant country finerefore exports resource intensive goods, and imports goods finat are intensive in fine use of capital and labor. In fine jargon of trade fineory, a resource-abundant country has a comparative advantage in producing pollution-intensive goods. The Stolper-Samuelson fineorem states fine direction in which factor intensities move when fine relative output prices change, be finis as a result of trade liberalization or a shift in fine demarnd curve (Stolper and Samuelson 1941). An increase in fine relative price of fine environmentally intensive good raises fine demand for environment as an input factor and wifin it, its price. An adjustment process takes place finat equalizes marginal productivity to fine new 16 price 1 ans-tron: taking l: Howey: good in slgnsiffi price levels. This adjustnnnent means a substitution away from fine more expensive environmental irnput towards the now cheaper capital and labor input This substitution is taking place in bofin irndustries so finat finey will bofin be less resource-intensive filan before. However, fine overall use of resources will not fall, because fine share of fine resource-intensive good in fine overall output increases. Obviously, fine same process takes place wifin opposite signs if fine original change is a drop in fine price of fine resource intensive good. The finird important fineorem of trade is fine Rybczynski (1955) fineorenn It deals wifin fine question of what happens if one of fine endowments of a country changes. An irncrease in fine availability of natural resources brings fine intuitive result finat production of fine environmentally intensive good will expand. Less intuitively, but as a direct result of fine above listed assumptions, fine production of fine capital and labor intensive good shrinks. If fine country is previously a net exporter of the pollution-intensive good, its exports will rise furfiner, as will its imports. If fine country is an importer of fine pollution intensive good, fine good will be substituted for by home production and fine trade volume will drop. The Rybczynski fineorem means finerefore finat specialization increases as fine differences in endowments between countries become larger. A country finat sets strict emission standards finerefore exports its pollution problem via trade. Conversely, in an open economy ofiner countries share fine benefits of increased output finat may result from lax emission standards. The finree fileorems finat result fiom fine Heckscher-Olnlin model are based on quite restrictive assumptions. However, file fiamework has served as a starting point for much of fine fineoretical literature on trade and environment. Next to fine elegance of fine model, its attractiveness lies in fine modeling assumptions themselves, which make initial factor endowments carry fine entire burden of fine explanation of trade patterns. If environment is 17 countrie Mexico, Onecou simply interpreted as if it is also a factor endowment, fine efl‘ects of a change in policy can be irntepreted in a straightforward manner. Most models, however, have moved beyond finis two- cornmodity, two-factor, two-country world finat fornns the core of classical trade fineory. In fine followirng review, it is mostly assumed finat trade takes place between two stylized countries wifin unequal endowments, because fine political concern about fine environment-trade irnteractiorn is centered around asymmetric alliances, such as finose between fine USA arnd Mexico, between Europe's North and Soufin, or between OECD countries and fine Third World One courntry is finerefore presumed to be rich and well-endowed wifin capital, but relatively scarce in labor and in environmental endowment, reflecting its comparatively strict pollution regulations. The ofiner country is taken to represent a prototype of a Third World courntry, wifin little capital, many working hands, and lax environmental regulations. Alfinough finis caricature of a trade agreement is not stricfiy needed for fine fineoretical analysis it is useful irn focussing fine discussion on fine cases most relevant to fine problem. Alfinough it is not strictly an environmental paper, Jones (1971) provides an important early contribution to fine issue, by presenting an analysis of fine Heckscher-Ohlin fiamework wifin finree instead of two input factors. In his analysis, only labor can be used for fine production of bofin outputs, while capital is only used for one good, and land (environment) is used exclusively for fine production of fine ofiner output. An important conclusion of his analysis is finat fine factor price adjustment mecharnism need not hold true. This conclusiorn mearns finat factor prices are not uniquely determined by fine price level of outputs, but also by fine general availability of factors wifinin an individual country. Even in a trade equilibrium wifin equal prices for goods, fine rewards for factors between two countries can difi‘er. A greater supply of environmental goods finus can entail an increase in fine compensation for ofiner factors. 18 throughoa model, g: directly tr It is consistent wifin Jones's model finat the return to bofin labor and capital was finroughout history persistently higher in file United States finan in Britain, as fine US had a greater abundance of natural resources, especially land. Under fine assumptions of Jones' rrnodel, govemment policies finat regulate fine availability of environmental inputs finus afl‘ect directly fine wage rate and interest rate of a country. Jones shows finat finis seemingly minor generalization of fine Heckscher-Ohlin model leads potentially to different policy cornclusions. For a small country in fine Heckscher-Ohlin model, fine reward for one input stays unafl‘ected by changes in fine supply of fine ofiner input. It is of no sigrnificance for owners of inputs, if finey live in a country wifin resource abundance or not. Due to its limitation in fine movement of factors between sectors, Jones's model produces fine result finat it very well matters for fine returrn on labor and capital what environmental regime rules the availability of resources. Capitalists' and workers' incomes depend here on fine restrictiveness of environmental policy. Itslnouldbenotedherefinatusuallyfine factorretumsdonotreactinasymmetrical way. The extent to which a certain factor benefits fiom a decrease in fine price of fine natural resource is positively related to two econonnic parameters, namely fine factor intensities arid fine elasticities of substitution: Iffine goods filat are intensive in fine use of environmental irnputs are also relatively intensive in labor inputs, labor will overproportionally profit from lower resource prices. In addition, a great elasticity of substitution between labor and environment (compared to finat between capital and environment) will benefit labor. The higher finis elasticity difi‘erence is, fine more labor flows towards fine resource-using sector in order to equalize productivity of resources among sectors. Movement of labor out of fine capital-using sector lowers fine productivity of capital. In fine extreme case, fine net return to capital may even fall, depending on fine model parameters. The reverse case can be made analogously. The ambivalence in fine 19 net results in Jones' model stresses fine furndamerntal importance of having good empirical estimates of input substitution possibilities and factor intensities, in order to avoid qualitative erors in fine analysis. McGuire (1982) shows finat factor-price equalization breaks down as countries implement different environmental regulations, which he models as neutral technical regress. Regulatory difi‘erences violate fine condition of identical technologies in the standard rrnodel. In contrast to Jones, however, in McGuire's model fine reward for file factor used intensively irn fine non-regulated industry will increase urnambiguously. While giving clear proof of fine possibility of deviations fiom fine factor-pnce-equalization fineorerrn, fine use of Jones' arnd McGuire's analysis for policy conclusions has limitations in finat fine analysis takes important parameters as externally given even finough finese parameters are really influenced by fine policy itself. One critical assumption is finat output prices are not influenced by domestic policy. In fine case of NAFI' A or fine European Union, for at least some sectors, fine assumptiorn carnrnot hold finat price levels will remain unaffected by changes in fine national environmental policies. Of course, fine degree to which competitiveness is changed depends not simply on fine permissible emissions but also on fine type of environmental policies chosen. For irnstance, an industry might be nnore sensitive to a tax instrument finan to a regulation. Clearly, however, irnsofar 3 environmental policies alter fine competitive position of an econonnic sector of a country, fine analysis will have to include effects on fine balance of payments and fine terms of trade. Furfinermore, as factor rewards change, factors supplies generally also change. Demand growfin for a pollution-intensive good raises fine productive value of pollution Cornsequenfiy pollution tends to rise. The assumption of fixed factor supply in fine Heckscher-Ohlin model, however, implies filat changing price levels do not affect fine level of environmental quality of a 20 mum maiys ObVlOL' and 01 under ti lax regt Mesa overall p coma}, v yerSl'orl of in It Qumran 0 meme. 8 Producuon production Pinning ch belt625:0, Sufi We “Moll courntry. A step towards incorporating demand and factor supply efi‘ects is urndertaken in fine analysis of Baumol and Oates (1988). The authors consider a model finat is based on fine aggregation of fine supply and demand curves of two trading countries. Assume finat a country induces an upward shift in fine supply curve of its pollution intensive good by imposing stricter environmental regulations. This increases fine global price level of fine polluting good, and reduces fine quantity cornsumed Obviously, fine pollution level irn fine home country will be reduced. The proposition by Baumol arnd Oates finat fine global pollution level must fall, however, seems to hold urnambiguously only under fine limiting assumption finat fine country finat increases fine regulatory stringency has rrnore lax regulations finarn fine ofiner country. It is conceivable, however, finat in some sectors an increase irn fine environmental standards of fine more regulated courntry leads to an increase in overall pollution ennissions, if it induces an increase in pollution-intensive production in fine courntry wifin fine less stringent regulation. It would be straightforward to construct a nnodified version of fine Baumol and Oates model finat produces finis result. In fine model, fine balance-of-payments effect on environmental regulation depends on fine question of whefiner fine regulating economy is a net importer or exporter of fine pollution- irntensive good. For importing countries fine balance of payments will deteriorate as home production falls and fine price level of imports increases. For exporters, decreases irn home productiorn arnd price increases point in opposite directions. The direction of balance-of- payments changes is finerefore not clear a priori. Also, whefiner non-environmental factors benefit or sufl‘er urnder regulatory policies will depend on fine shape of fine demand curve. A low price elasticity of demand can mean that fine return to labor and capital actually rises, as. fine sector extracts a quasi-monopoly rent from its price increase. 21 In fine same way as fine Jones model cautions us to consider fine irrnportance of input substitution elasticities in deriving qualitative results, fine Baumol-Oates model stresses file sensitivity of modelling to demand elasticities. The sensitivity of fine result to elasticities may be even furthered by fine omission in bofin models of substitutiorns in demand between difl‘erenfiy polluting goods. If fine government regulates one sector only, fine pollution level may actually rise (even wifinin a country) as fine pollution reduction in one sector may be overcompensated by fine pollution increase in anofiner sector. 1.4.2. Factor Mobility and the Industrial Flight Hypothesis The results presented are based on models finat use fine critical assumption finat factors of production are internationally immobile. In most cases, such as fine European Union and NAFTA, fine assumption of capital immobility is, however, unrealistic. Mundell (1957) has shown finat movements in factors can substitute for fine movement in commodities and lead to an identical price-equalization phenomenon as in fine Heckscher-Ohlin fiarnework. In a two- factor/two-good world, fine mobility of only one factor is needed to produce fine result Ifcapital is fine mobile factor, it would move into fine capital-scarce country until factor-price equalization is reached. The capital-abundant country loses productiorn, while fine labor- abundant country increases overall production. As a firm has fine choice of eifiner servirng a foreign market finrough exports or finrough production in fine foreign market, capital flows in general will reduce fine level of trade between countries, alfinough it is possible finat investrnert and trade are supplements (Markusen 1983; Wong 1986). McGuire (1982) demonstrates finat, in a Heckscher-Ohlin type model, fine regulated industry will be completely driven out of fine regulating country. If fine factor finat is used intensively in fine regulated sector is internationally mobile, it will migrate out of fine regulating 22 in the l benefit a facton standar mobile capital f than offs a! subset and the s aWOprn'al Swims ft increase. country and fine overall economy will shrink, not only due to fine decreased productivity entailed in fine regulation, but also due to fine loss in fine production factor. If, however, file mobile factor benefits fiom fine regulation, because it is not used intensively, a regulation can actually induce a factor inflow innto fine regulating economy. Alfinough one would expect fine first case to be fine standard scenario, an economy could actually gain under a certain set of economic parameters. Merrifield (1988) also provides an example of a model of pollution abatement with mobile capital. A tax on fine polluting industries could actually increase pollutiorn, because capital flows into fine ofiner country, and fine consequent increase in pollution finere may nnore finan ofl‘set fine reduction in errnissions at home. The effect depends crucially on fine elasticities of substitution among factor inputs, pollution and capital intensities in production furnctions, arnd fine sensitivity of fine capital stock to pollution damage wifinin each country. Given fine appropriate parameters, fine model of Merrifield is finus capable of producing fine nightmare scenario for rich countries: An increase in standards produces a loss of jobs while pollution increases. Worries of trade urnions and many environmentalists in wealfiny countries about trade liberalization wifin poorer nations are based exactly on finis reasoning of fine mixed commodity- factor flow nnodel. Of fine finree factors of production finat we consider, poorer countries can be assumed to have an abundance in fine two finat are immobile (resources and labor), while finey have a scarcity in fine mobile factor (capital). To equalize factor rewards, capital will finerefore move fiom fine rich country to fine poor where it is scarce, and hence earns a larger return In fine extreme, fine poorer economy grows and fine wealfinier economy shrinks due to fine capital flows. 23 In the production: loss through- problem fin: country rm; manic n mobility lea environmen In fine aseptic world of Heckscher-Ohlin models, finere is no tragedy in fine loss of production as fine population of fine country wifin capital outflow gets overcompensated for fineir loss finrough fine higher rent finey obtain in fine foreign rrnarket In real life finere is, of course, fine problen finat capital owners and workers are not identical. A move of capital outside of a courntry implies direct job or earning loss and depresses fine home country’s (Keynesian) economic multiplier and its tax base. The ramifications of fine standard model wifin capital nnobility leave policymakers only fine choice of taking a wage loss or of harrnornizing fine environmental standards. There are a number of reasons, however, why the capital mobility model need not lead to an exodus of capital into fine country that ofi‘ers low wages and environmental costs. One important factor is finat a firm's decision to relocate depends on more parameters finan fine firree factors listed Notably, the model neglects finat labor is hardly homogenous. Know-how and human capital are often more important for a production process finan fine numbe of working hands. While most poor countries are surely well-endowed wifin unskilled labor, finis condition is generally accomparnied by a relative scarcity of skilled workers. For many firms, finis scarcity is fine decisive constraint not to relocate. Ofiner factors, such as cultural barriers, political stability, quality of public infiastructure and commurnications firms, bureaucratic idiosyncracies, or even fine low level of environmental quality, may be important factors finat combine to create an industrial inertia finat keeps companies from writing 05 fine physical and human capital of existing companies in fine home country. The value of low environmental regulations in fine host country also may be overrmd as a factor for industrial location, since companies plan fineir pollution standards to meet standards finat apply for fine life span of fine investment. As retrofitting of old equipment tends to be very 24 “pensive, government: environment come 2 this context 1 than to dom- felocate for economic irr barrierto cm Pmductjvhy 0f know-hoe ”my, and me and the Simple mode pmduCtix-tty flow, not le; mmc fin! expensive, firms will mostly orient themselves to meet expected regulations." oaen governmental rhetoric and anecdotal evidence point towards an increased stringency of environmental regulatiorns. Even in fine absence of regulatory enforcement, large international connparnies generally try to meet global environmental standards. Leonard (1988) points out in finis context finat many countries tend to apply stricter environmental standards to foreign rafiner finan to domestic firms. These general remarks do not imply finat finere are no companies finat relocate for purely environmental reasons as fine fineory would predict, but rafiner finat fineir economic importance tends to be limited. By fine same token high investment costs can act as a barrier to entry for new firms, which also cannot be measures directly. The fineoretical importance of capital flows is also dependent on difi‘erences in productivity between fine country of origin and fine receiving country. Capital flows and flows of know-how are usually tied to each ofiner. If investment flows afi‘ect productivity in fine poorer country, and wifin it fine purchasing power, it may actually be increasing rafiner finan decreasing trade and fine wage rate-even for unskilled laboruin the richer country. In fine fiamework of a simple model, Wong (1986) lists fine necessary conditions for finis. The positive feedbacks fiom productivity improvement may finus to a considerable extent benefit fine richer country's trade flow, not least because international transplants tend to have a larger import share finan domestic firms. 7 For chenical firms, Monty states finat the capital investment necessary for pollution reduction on existing plants is rouglnly five times as expensive as fine equivalent equipment installation in a new plant (Monty 1991, p.7). 25 critically ill ofcapital f lamented b The ] levels of en be fornnnular is a fundam regulators. depend on ii 1.43. Empi Empir Despite fine acknowledgement in fine theoretical literature that capital mobility can critically alter fine qualitative results of trade liberalization, an appropriate numerical modeling of capital flows is very dificult. The omission of fine problem in most applied models has been lamented by several aufinors (Srinivasan and Whalley 1986, Goulder and Eichengreen 1992). The precedirng review of fine literature presents fine traditional arguments of how difl‘erent levels of environmental regulation shape fine pattern of trade specialization. This argument can be formulated as fine “industrial flight hypofinesis”. It maintains finat high pollution-control costs is a fundamental factor in making firms leave nations which have a high level of environmental regulations. Evidently, the link between pollution control costs and actual emissions will depend on fine type of environmental policy in place. 1.4.3. Empirical Findings on Industrial Flight Hypothesis Empirical studies on industrial flight hypofinesis have to cope wifin fine intrinsic dificulty of measuring levels of pollution and pollution control expenditures. Tacklirng filese severe data linnitations has produced a wide array of empirical methods. Different approaches range from fine merely descriptive, to econometric tests and simulation models. Kalt (1988) analyzes US trade flows fiom 1967 to 1977 in a cross-country regression His findings point to an insignificant impact of environmental regulation on all sectors. However, if fine analysis is limited to fine manufacturing, a clear negative impact on exports due to regulation is established. This impact becomes even more significant, if fine chemical sector is excluded from fine manufacturing aggregate. In analyzing fine pollution content of trade flows, Robison (1988) finds finat increases in pollution control have shifted fine comparative advantage of fine United States witln Canada More high-abatement—cost goods are imported and more low-abatement cost goods are 26 Wong discount starts bet turbulenc even with L’su of a group 00¢ Changer Calm}, l5 Sign exported While finere is no doubt about finis trend, fine value of fine study needs to be discounted on fine grounds finat it has fine implicit assumption finat standards remained urnchanged in Canada Furfinermore, fine analysis could be potentially biased by fine timing of fine years for which the abatement content of trade was calculated. The time span analyzed stars before fine First Oil Crisis (1973) and shortly after fire Second Oil Crisis (1982). The turbulences of fine world trade system at fine time may have caused changing trade patterns, even wifinout changing environmental policies. Using a similar mefinodology as Robison, Sorsa (1994) shows finat world market shares of a group of countries with high industrial standards in environmentally sensitive goods have not changed much over fire last two decades. Wifin fine exception of a changing composition of trade wifin Eastern Europe, Scherp and Suardi (1997) find also finat fine relative pollution intensity of EU trade has not changed and may have even increased since fine 19705. This result contrasts wifin fine study by Tobey (1990). He identifies ”dirty" irndustries according to fine percentage of abatement expenditures per sector. From finis criterion he derives fine pollution content of a country‘s exports, which is regressed on is resource endowmens. The inclusion of a dummy variable finat measures environmental stringency of fine courntny does not yield any statistically significant impact of environmental regulation on trade patterns. Van Beers and van den Bergh (1996) develop fine approach used by Tobey furtlner and derive a rrnore differentiated result A broad indicator of environmental policy in fine exporting courntry is significant, but has a positive sign. This positive sign means, environmental policy irncreases fine country’s export However, a narrower indicator of environmental policy developed by fine authors shows a significant but negative sign on aggregate trade flows. Most 27 nhztrnrc fo Sim Wigle 199 of trade. I of: tax fin: US. He re Low remain linens. importantly, they find a significant negative relationship for highly pollution intensive sectors that are footloose. Simulation models (Walter 1973, D'Arge 1974; OECD 1978; Pearson 1987; Perroni and Wigle 1995) predict small but discernible efi‘ects of pollution control measures on the balance of trade. Tackling the problem in a simulation model, Low (1992) analyzes the consequences of a tax that equates pollution abatement and control expenditures of Mexico with those of the U.S. He reports that his simulations show only negligible effects on Mexican exports. Since Low remains vague about the structural details of the simulation itself, it is difiicult to judge its merits. Location-of-industry studies also provide some insights. The literature is related to studies measuring the locational impact of taxes. Newman and Sullivan (1988) provide a literature review on this type of study. The existing consensus is that differences in taxes are of importance in the intraregional location of firms, while its influence on location decisions between regions is insignificant. Newman and Sullivan, however, consider the latter point to be far from settled There are formidable econometric problems involved in estimating the tax impacts. Mainly, these problems involve the fact that the celeris paribus condition does not hold Businesses in general do not mind high taxes, if the local government uses the revenue to provide for services such as a good infrastructure and a good local education level. Taxes that are used for redistributional purposes will be regarded unfavorably. In general, the ceten's paribus variables will be decisive in determining the location of a firm, and this conclusion makes it diflicult to isolate the independent influence of taxes. This dificulty is even more pronounced in the case of environmental regulations, which are usually portrayed of having a small role compared to other factors (cp. Motta and Thisse 1993). 28 0n the receiving end, Birdsall and Wheeler (1992) state an increase in international investment in pollution-intensive industries in Latin America because of stricter OECD rules. Molina (1993) suggests a clear relationship between abatement costs and the growth of Mexico's maquiladora industry. Instead of following other studies in regressing abatement costs on the distribution of industries, he regresses abatement on the growth of difl'erent industry sectors in the Rio Grande area Molina finds that those sectors with the highest share of abatement costs were the fastest to expand their activities in the Mexican maquila industry. Indirectly, this may imply a certain degree of industrial flight fiom the US or elsewhere, although a correlation need not imply causality. Xing and Kolstad (1997) also arrived at the conclusion that more lax environmental regulations in a host country were significantly correlated with US chemical industry investments. For other industry this link could not be shown. However, they find hints that relaxed environmental regulations in the host country are correlated with higher overall investments by US firms. Bouman (1996) finds for Germany that compliance costs are slightly related to capital outflows. However, these results are highly dependent on model specifications. McConnell and Schwab (1990) indicate that difi‘erences in environmental regulations among counties in the United States do not appear to influence investment decisions significantly. The empirical evidence for the impact of pollution restrictions on location corresponds to that of short-run tax incentives, a result that is not surprising in light of the 29 similar nature of environmental regulations and taxes as business incentives'. On an international level, locational decisions are mostly driven by agglomeration economies, such as infi'astructure and other existing industries, with some level of importance attached to classical parameters like market size and labor costs (Wheeler and Mody 1992). No study seems to state conclusively whether there is a positive, negative, or zero correlation between capital flows and pollution abatement costs. This conclusion is due to the low number of observations used in most studies, as well as a variety of estimation problems. For the high-polluting sectors such as mineral processing, chemicals, pulp and paper, mid petroleum, pollution control equipment can cost between roughly 10 and 24 %of new plant equipment in OECD countries (Lucas er alii 1992). For these industries, a relocation response to lower environmental standards would not be surprising. This, however, would only concern new factories, not existing ones. Pollution abatement operating costs as a percentage of output value lies in the United States at 0.54 % on average, with the highest value at 3.17 °/o (Low 1992, 113-4). The low level of these numbers do not point to a mass exodus of United States industry due to difl‘erences in environmental regulation. It has been pointed out, however, by Chapman (1991) that regulation costs are highly underestimated, because the figures do not include items such as workplace health and safety protection costs. A possible counterargument is that these costs could equally be seen as hidden labor costs. This seemingly academic statement points to the problem that if dirty 'Thereisanemergingconsensusintheliteraturethattaxesareamoreimportantissuein intrametropolitan location decisions than in intermetropolitan decisions (McConnell and Schwab 1990). 30 industries are also labor intensive ones, it will be dificult to separate that reason for the relocation of an industry. A statistical regression thus encounters the problem of multicollinearity, in addition to the unavoidable distortions of pressing the complex decisionmaking process for a firm’s location into a simple mathematical model. The argument by Chapman, however, finds support in the study of Gray and Shadbegian (1993). Using a plant-level data set, they find that, statistically, a one-dollar increase in regulation costs is associated with a 3-to—4-dollar drop in productivity. Using these results, the authors find that environmental compliance costs have reduced the average total factor productivity in the paper, oil, and steel industries by 5.3, 3.1, and 7.6 %, respectively. These results appear to be at a higher level of plausibility than those quoted by Low, although they surely will not be the last words written on the subject. Stafl‘ord (1985) uses an approach that circumvents the problem of potentially unreliable pollution cost figures by using personal interviews and questionnaires to identify the factors that were most important for large U.S. corporations in locating their branch plants. The result of the study is that difl‘erences in environmental regulations have some influence on location decisions, but rank behind other factors, like labor characteristics, markets, transportation, materials, infrastructure, quality of life, business climate, community characteristics, and taxes. Even for plant types that are qualified as "less clean”, the influence of environmental regulations is outweighed by markets, labor, and materials. The influence of regulations seems to be of slightly more importance for the choice of the exact plant site on a local level than on a regional level. The influence of environmental regulations therefore mirrors the influence of taxes on industrial regulation. Stafl‘ord's results converge with those of other econometric studies. 31 However, Stafi‘ord's study may underestimate the relocation problem, because the firms in the sample are all members of the Fortune 500. Large enterprises that run a large number of factories will mually avoid the bad publicity of nrnning a hazardous plant The operation of a plant like Union Carbide's Bhopal generally does not make good business sense for the mother company. Large companies therefore have a tendency to use uniform standards at all production facilities (Pearson 1987; Warhurst and Isnor 1996, Levy 1995, Leonard 1988). Multinational enterprises generally seek consistent environmental enforcement rather than lax enforcement Jafl‘e er a1. (1995) summarize intra-US locations studies. The studies summarized find either no significant or very small effects in particular circumstances. There are even hints that low environmental standards can even discourage investment. A statistical problem that might lead to an understatement of the problem is that it compares only locations within the United States with only a limited variation in environmental relations. There is some reason to believe that the firms for which lax pollution standards are an overwhelming factor are not part of the sample because they invest abroad In the framework of the industrial flight hypothesis, this approach means that firms are only surveyed if they did not leave the country. Leonard's (1988) study must thus be seen as complementary to that of Stafl‘ord, as he analyzes case studies of U.S. firms that left the country. He also finds that, while lax environmental regulations may help to gain a locational advantage, they are usually overwhelmed by other factors. Stafi‘ord provides two important insights by disaggregating the general locational influence of environmental regulation of the firm's decision into its component. The first is that it is not the allowable level of pollution emissions that deters companies, but the level of 32 uncertainty and delay that is involved with the bureaucratic process of obtaining an operating license. The number of required permits are more important than the capital costs of pollution control. This is related to the second irnsight that firms see environmental regulations as part of a regulatory package. In other words, a helpful bureaucracy that is perceived as pro business will not loose business through strict regulations, as long as it has a clear and quick permit- granting process. This harmonizes also with the finding of Duerksen and Leonard (1930) that most of the relocation taking place due to regulatory difi‘erences flows into other industrialized countries, and not into less-developed countries. Obviously, low emissions standards alorne do not sufice in gainirng capital inflows. It has been correctly pointed out by Pearson (1987) that it is not a priori clear to believe that the increased output of an environmentally abundant country will be captured by multinationals as opposed to domestic firms. An analysis of the locational patterns of international firms may therefore be the wrong place to look for a solution of the industrial relocation issue. The question of regulation-induced industrial relocation is therefore not yet settled, although there is an indication that it plays some role for especially polluting sectors, as Molina (1993) and Birdsall and Wheeler (1992) suggest. In summary, it appears that, for the economy as a whole, the fears of industrial flight are largely exaggerated Comparative advantage in environmental regulatiorns appeals to play a role for the location of only a limited set of industries, and is a minor factor for industry in gerneral. Heckscher-Ohlin type trade models (at least in their naive form) are fournd warnting in predicting the efl‘ects of regulations on trade patterns. While of concern for trade tlneorists, these empirical findings are reassuring for ecologically minded govemmernts. Due to the mirnor 33 influence of regulations on industrial location, it appears that trade and environmental goals can be pursued largely independently. 1.4.4. Pollution Haven Hypothesis Related to the industrial flight hypotlnesis is the pollution haven hypotlnesis. It states tlnat irn an open economy governments are willing to lower ernvrionmental standards to give a trade advantage to domestic sectors. In merging the findings of the environmental literature with trade tlneories, several papers are careful to point out that, in an open economy, an optimal environmental tax is not simply a matter of applying the Pigou theorem (i.e. imposing a marginal emissions charge equal to the marginal extemality).9 the seminal paper was written by Markusen (1975), which addresses the problem in a two-country, two-commodity general equilibrium framework with no substitution possibilities for the production of the polluting good. A Pigouvian tax should be equal to domestic external costs, while the optimal tarifl‘ combines the standard optimal tarifl‘ with an additional charge that reflects the extemality that results from the pollution imported from foreigrn production. Clearly in this case, the transboundary pollution increases the optimal tarifl' beyond the level that would prevail in its absence. The Pigouvian tax, however, remains too low to produce a global social optimum. Krutilla (1991) shows that there are at least two other factors that are to be included in the determination of an optimal pollution tax, even without transboundary flows of pollutants. ’Opfimalrefersheretotheopfinnalpohcyoftheirnposingcountryonly,notwlnatwouldbe optimalunderaglobalwelfarefunction. 34 Thefirstistheefl‘ectofanenvironmentaltaxonthetermsoftradeofacountrythatwas already mentioned in the discussion of Baumol and Oates; the otlner is the efi’ect on tarifl' revenue. Both have opposing signs and depend on the position of a country as net exporter or importer of the taxed good, as well as the question of whether the associated extemality occurs during its production or consumption. Taxing a production extemality in a country produces benefits by reducirng tlne extemality. Iftlne country is a net exporter of the polluting good, it also benefits fi'om improving the terms of trade, thus the tax generates a monopolistic surplus gain on the reduced export volume. An optimal tax tlnus needs to include the terms-of-trade efi‘ects, and is higlner than the Pigouvian tax for the net exporter. This result is a standard conclusion of trade and environment modeling (see for example Markusen 1975; Rauscher,l993). The terms of trade efi‘ect is large, if the country's supply elasticity is. high and the export elasticity is low. If the country is a net importer of the polluting good, the terms of trade efl‘ect works to lower the optimal tax below the Pigouvian level, as the country now suffers a terms-of-trade loss tlnrough increased and more expensive imports. There is a second efi‘ect, however, which works in the opposite direction of the terms-of- trade efl‘ect In the case of a net exporter, a pollution tax reduces the volume of trade and with it the country's tarifl~ revenues shrink. This efl‘ect increases with the tariff rate and does not exist, if the level of tariffs is zero. Krutilla thus hints at the importance of fiscal variables for the analysis of trade and environment interactions. It should be pointed out here tlnat the analysis remains partial and tlnus incomplete, in that it ignores how the tariff revenues are spent. (As tarifi' revenues will shrink and pollution taxes increase, the overall direction of tlne public 35 budget is undetermined.) The argument for a general equilibrium analysis will be explored later. The analysis of Krutilla has been carried further by Kennedy (1993). Kenrnedy difi'ers from Krutilla in three crucial points. First and most importantly, Kennedy models strategic interactions between two large trading countries in a game-fineoretic framework. This approach meanns that the analysis moves away from the somewhat urnrealistic assumption that the ofiner country does not react to the policy measures in the home country. Whether the assumption of a given-and known—reaction curve by Kennedy is more realistic is another matter. However, it points out the great importance of strategic interactions between countries. The analysis deviates from Krutilla further in that it assumes imperfect competitiorn, while Krutilla assumes a perfect-competition economy with the import or export status of a country exogenously given. Thirdly, the inclusiorn of transbourndary pollution accentuates the interaction between the two countries in a strategic sense, since the stakes for each country are higher. The analysis is a modification of the optimal tarifi‘ literature. Tlnree efl'ects drive fine decision concerning the optimal tax on pollution away fiom the Pigouvian solution. First, there is the rent-capture effect. This efl‘ect denotes the change in the surplus generated fiom foreigners, and includes changes in profits from exports as well as changes in tax revenues from exports. In Kennedy's model, this efi‘ect is negative, since increased taxes reduce fine level of exports. Most interestingly, while finis effect drives fine tax level up in Krutilla's analysis, Kennedy finds it to reduce fine opfimal tax level. He attributes it to fine fact finat, in Krutilla's model, trade flows are determined exogenously by traditional forces such as comparative advantage. Facirng competitive buyers, fine net exporting country is free to use a tax as a means to extract a 36 mornopoly rent from fine buyers. In Kennedy's framework, fine direction of trade is determined exclusively by relative tax rates. The country (that is ofinerwise equal) which has fine lower tax rate will finerefore be an exporter, while fine ofiner will be an importer. The implications of finese nnodelirng differences are quite fundamental, since Krutilla suggests finat free trade will not provide an incentive to lower pollution standards, while Kennedy provides ammunition for fine side finat argues against free trade on fine basis that it would erode environmental standards. Certainly, finere are examples of industries finat support fine arguments on eifiner side. In fine cases of an asymmetrical trade integration between poor and rich countries, Kennedy's assumption that bofin countries have identical endowments is not tenable. Tlnere may finus be room for fine extraction of monopoly profits from one country, at least in certain industries. On fire ofiner hand, wifin some likelihood, finere are industries where fine competitive situation in fine difl‘erent countries is quite similar. Differences in environmental regulations may therefore tilt fine balance in favor of one or fine ofiner country, finus lending plausibility to Kennedy's analysis. Clearly, some analysis or educated guesswork of fine compefitive structure of key industrial sectors is necessary to detennine fine net benefits of environmental policies in a free-trade arrangement. In practice, fine respective political strength of fine potential winners and losers will be decisive in determining fine direction in which fine rent capture efi‘ect will point fine environmental regulations. Two more shifters of environmental policy are identified by Kennedy. The trarnsboundary efl'ect keeps fine optimal tax rate below Pigouvian levels, because a country’s policy does not acconmt for fine pollution finat causes damage in ofiner countries. This effect occurs wifin or wifinout trade. The last effect listed is fine familiar pollute-finy-neighbor-via-trade 37 efi‘ect, which works to make fine pollution policy more stringent finan warranted by Pigouvian policy (Siebert 1935). Using a dual general equilibrium approach to produce results comparable to that of Kennedy, Ulph (1990) finds finat quantity irnstrument are Pareto superior over fine tax instrument The conclusion by Ulph is biased, however, through fine fact that it is a partial analysisfinatneglectsfinatfinemoneyeamedwithfinetaxinstrumentmaybeputintoauseofiner than paying for an urnproductive state apparatus, and finus needs to enter welfare considerations. Furfiner models include dynamic interactions between countries. These models try to overcome the assumption in a comparative static analysis that trade flows are detemnined solely on fine base of factor endowments. Implicit in fine traditional trade theory is finerefore fine assumption finat, once a comparative advantage in endowments disappears, trade flows will revert If finis assumption were true, it would be foolish for a government to subsidize fire location of a certain industry, because firms would only stay as long as fine subsidy is grannted In fine economic system of fine Heckscher-Ohlin paradign, history does not matter. Once fine initial parameters are replicated, exactly fine same structure will be reproduced Economic gowfin is, however, pafin dependent Through changes in price levels and fine structure of competitiorn, trade can lead to fine formation of econonnies of size and technological innovation. Many government planners finerefore believe that locational advantages are self- perpetuating. Efl‘ects, such as leaming-by-doing and agglomeration economies (i.e., fire costs and benefits of geographical concentration) may change fire economic structure of a courntry permanenfiy. Much of fine difference between classical trade theory and recent fineoretical developments lies in fine acknowledgement of fine importance of fine development pafin. 38 Porter (1991; Porter and van der Linde 1995) has turned fine argument arournd arnd fornnrulated fine hypofinesis finat countries can use fine early introduction of environmental policies strategically to give domestic environmental industries a head start compared to foreign competitors. The idea behind fine Porter hypofinesis is finat irn countries finat regulate early and well (1), companies can move down fine leanring curve wifinout large market losses to non-regulated competitors. However, by fine time competitors start to regulate finey will have developed a strong competitive edge. There are many caveats linked to fine hypothesis. Most rnotably, it fails to provide any ex ante information on what regulations will be beneficial. For a criticism of fire Porter Hypofinesis, see Palmer et al. (1995). Their critique relies basically on fine fact that firms could spot future business opportunities in fine environmental field even wifinout fine government. There are numerous extensiorns to fine game fineoretic literature finat analyze fine problem of organizing fire world's countries to cope wifin trarnsboundary pollution, especially global warming However, fine problem of global commons exceeds fine scope of finis paper, whicln focuses on domestic pollution only. While dynamic and game-fineoretic effects are of importance, finey are intrinsically dificult to model, and have yielded limited insights in fine sense of falsifiable predictiorns about what governments actually do. Especially, game-fineoretic models tend to be intellectually stimulating mind games wifin no attempt at corroborating fineir insights wifin empirical observations. What finere is in empirical literature shows little evidence that governments cornsciously use environmental regulations as irnstruments of trade-related policy goals in fine form of "ecological dumping", an irnsight which probably is not urnrelated to fine limited efi‘ect such a policy seems to have on fine location of industries. 39 Rauscher (1993) caufions finat ecological dumping is not simply identical to having lower environmental standards finan ofiner countries. As has been pointed out, finere is no reason why environmental regulations should be equal in all countries, since preferences. and national endowments vary among regions. The normative statement finat regulations should be identical around fine world is to be rejected on firese grounds. Difl‘erences in environmental regulations (at least for local pollution) may be even desirable, as it leads to global welfare increases due to the principles of comparative advantage. Ecological dumping is also not identical wifir pricing of pollution below marginal social damage. While finis pricing certainly produces economic distortions it is not necessarily due to a conscious decision to change trade patterns, but can have many other motivations. on a practical level, Rauscher proposes a finird defirnitiorn, which states finat ecological dumping occurs wherever fine (explicit or implicit) price of environmental resources is lower irn fine tradeables finan in fine non-tradeables sector. Under finis definition, fine level of infonnatiorn needed to test for fine existence of environmental policies as a means to gain a trade advantage is considerably less finan finat for fine previous definition. It is not necessary to urndertake fine near-impossible task of analyzing a correct resource price. Instead, one can simply focus on price and regulatory differences. F urther, Rauscher's finird definition seems to be fine most realistic way policymakers would try to take strategic advantage of low regulation levels in a trade setting. To my knowledge, finere exists no study finat analyzes mefinodically, fine question of whefirer states systematically follow a policy of ecological dumping in fine sense of Rauscher, alfirough anecdotal evidence exists. The most prominent example of finis kind is fine exploitation of tropical forests for export. In many cases, however, fine policy is not part of a deliberate 40 long-term plan, but emerges from short-term necessity. Of special importance here, is fine need to serve huge amounts of foreign debts that might lead Third World courntries often to underprice fineir natural resources (T udini 1993). Anofiner important area where deliberate discrimination applies is in fine field of energy/C02 taxation. Since energy can constitrrte a considerable cost component for certain industries, this is a field where efi‘ective tax rates can difi'er substantially. For fine global commons such a tax differentiation may even be beneficial as it reduces carbon leakage (Scherp and Suardi 1997). It should be noted here finat, for fine case of medium-income countries fire supposition of a pollution-haven strategy may not be fine only relevant of fine two hypotlneses for strategic environmental policy, as firey may be squeezed on botln sides. Higher environmental standards may decrease fine country's attractiveness for capital from rich countries, while its own industry moves towards courntries wifir even lower regulations. An answer to fine question of whefiner trade liberalization improves or deteriorates fine environment in medium-income countries, leaves open fire questiorn what takes place in ofiner countries. A pollution reduction wifinin fine free-trade area could mean finat fine polluting sectors move to finird countries finat are more willing to sell off fineir environment On a global level, pollution may finerefore still rise. There exists, however, to my krnowledge no fineoretical literature dealing wifin fine trade and environment complex in a finree-country fiarnework. 1.4.5. Empirical Evidence of the Pollution Haven Hypothesis In light of fine negligible efl‘ect of environmental regulations on trade flows it not surprising that finere is no evidence that countries systematically use environmental policy as a means of attracting business. Leonard (1988) screens numerous case studies of industrial relocations of U.S. firms into four industrializing countries for evidence of conscious ecological 41 dumping. While fine urnderpricing of environmental costs seems evident for fire case of Romania under Ceausescu, in ofiner countries fine evidence points largely to fine contrary. After attempts in fine 19505 to use lax environmental regulations as a means of attracting foreign investors, Ireland reversed finis policy, not least because it had only a small efi'ect on investors. For Mexico and Spain, Leonard finds fire contrary policy finat environmental regulations are mostly higher on foreign comparnies finan domestic ones. Historically, comparatively low environmental standards are often more fine result of ignorance finan of conscious decision making Leonard provides evidence that fire medium-income countries become increasingly nnore adept at obtaining environmental concession fiom foreign firms, as fine countries move down a learning curve. Murell and Rytennan (1991) analyze whefiner a comparative advantage in pollution- intensive products could serve as a justification for lax environmental standards. In particular, finey conclude finat fire relatively lax environmental policy in Eastern Europe carnrnot be explained by a tendency to export commodities intensive in pollution. 1.5. Poverty Attraction Hypothesis The empirical evidence compiled above indicates that fine two components of fine traditional pessimism hypofiresis have only a very limited backing in fine empirical literature. However, finis does not eliminate fine possibility finat trade among countries wifin urnequal level of development results in increased pollution levels. 1.5.1. Conditions for the Hypothesis While regulation-setting itself may not be important for industrial locationn, finere is a strong possibility finat regulations are correlated to other important location factors. Therefore, 42 trade could lead to higher overall emissions, if countries with low environmental standards specialize irn pollution intensive sectors, even if fine relaxed regulations finemselves play a minor role. Since low environmental standards can be found in developing countries and strict starndards in industrialized countries, the nature of Norfin-Soufin trade becomes crucial. This possibility leads directly to the formulation, of what could be labeled fine “poverty attraction hypofinesis”: pollution-intensive sectors tend to be attracted to poor countries. Free trade leads to environmental degradation in poor countries, because fine relocatiorn is met wifin lax environmental regulation. This concern has been formulated early by Walter and Ugelow (1979; see also Copeland and Taylor 1994 1995). Specialization need not be driven by environmental standards but result from exacerbating factors such labor and capital endowments. The fineoretical trade literature is of litfie help in determining fine expected specialization. Depending on fine correlatiorn of pollution- intensity with ofiner factors such as labor intensity and capital intensity, Norfin-Soufin specialization could occur in eifiner way. Development fineory ofi‘ers some assistance. It is well established finat as countries move finrough stages of development, their econonnies become less resource and labor based, and become increasingly capital intensive. However, again it remains an empirical question whefiner the donninant sectors of early development stages are intrinsically dirty or are polluting because of fine coincidentally low pollution standards. Furfinerrnore, it is an empirical question whefiner trade makes fine situation worse. 1.5.2. Empirical Findings on Poverty Attraction Hypothesis Empirical literature exists on bofin fine trade aspect and fine development aspect of fine poverty attraction argument The analysis of trade flows indicates that environmentalist fears of trade specialization are not completely unfounded. A number of empirical studies confirm finat 43 developing countries tend to specialize in dirty industries. Low and Yeats (1992) investigate fine cmnection between fine pollution content of trade and income level. They find finat exports of dirty products account for a growing share of developirng countries' exports. Ofiner econometric studies derive at similar results (Hettige et al. 1992; Birdsall and Wheeler 1992). Desus and Bussolo (1995) achieve finis conclusion using a computable general equilibrium model for Costa Rica By contrast, Sorsa (1994) shows finat industrialized and developing countries roughly maintained fineir comparative advantage in environmentally sensitive goods. Similarly, Schep arnd Suardi (1997) also find finat EU-T‘lnird World trade specialization was mostly unclnanged over 20 years. The assembled evidence is weakened by fine fact that all studies rely on the same emissions data set compiled by fire World Bank (Hettige et al. 1995) on which also this study draws. However, fine overall balance of fine empirical trade literature appears to indicate finat developing countries have a comparative advantage in pollution-intensive sectors. Potentially, this conclusion could imply finat it is not commendable for a Third World country to follow an open trade policy, because fine removal of trade barriers will lead to a worsening of a poor country's environmental and, in fine longer run, economic situation. The empirical literature of fine connection between pollution and development hints that fine relationship between a country’s wealfin and pollution follows an inverted U (Selder arnd Song 1994, 1995; World Bank 1992; Shafik 1994; Grossman and Krueger 1995; de Bruyn et 44 al. 1995, Lucas at al. 1992; Rock 1996; Xapappadeas and Amri 1998)”. This phenomenon is known also as environmental Kuzrnets curve. It denotes the observation that fine least developed courntries have relatively low levels of toxic release, countries undergoing industrialization are highly polluted, and post-industrial countries are relatively clean. Grossman and Krueger estimate finat fine highest level of pollution occurs for countries wifin a per capita income near USS 5,000 (at purchasing power parity) which is about fire income level of Mexico. Beyond this finreshold, increased GDP is correlated wifin a decrease in pollution, at least in fine cross-country data set. Radetzki (1992) notes additionally finat fine curve is moving down over time. A country today is cleaner than a country in a comparable ecornorrnic stage of development finirty years ago. The shape and time trend of fine curve is also fonnrnd by Goldemberg (1992) for the consumption of energy per unit of GDP which is ultimately fine source of most pollutants. However, finese findings are not uncontested: Apart fiom dificulties of comparing pollution levels across countries, it is neifiner clear where fine trnrning point rniglnt be located, nor does fine absolute level of pollution decline in all cases (Esty arnd Gentry 1998). The observation of fine inverted U curve does not allow to draw any direct inference on fine interaction between trade and environment, because it does not measure fine composition of the economy as a dependent variable. Rather, it looks directly at emissions which are obviously also influenced by. regulation levels. Furthermore, finere is no hint at whether trade has any impact on finis pattern. Therefore, fine findings provide little direct evidence for or against fine '° Lopez (1994) derives the result from a theoretical model. 45 poverty attraction hypofinesis. However, it points to fine critical nature of assumirng constant factor endowments and regulations. 1.6. Research Gaps and Purpose of this Paper The existing body of literature leaves finree important lacunae that will be parfiy filled by finis dissertation. First, finis paper will add to fine empirical literature on trade and environment interactions. Second, it is one of only very few studies finat explicitly include fine environmental extemality in fine analysis. Third, it treats integates fine political process of regulations in fine analysis. 1.6.1. Contribution to Empirical Research The literature on trade and environment has made substantial advances. Wifin fine notable exception of fine Porter hypofinesis, most fineoretical papers argue finat tighter regulations lead to a comparative disadvantage of fine regulated sectors. The important question is rafiner how important actually is fine influence of regulatiorns. The emerging consensus of fine empirical literature provides good and bad news. On fine one hand, industrial flight of relatively little importance. On fine ofiner hand, finere are some hints finat poor countries have a relative advarntage in polluting industries. This paper will take a fresh look at fine two hypofinesis in fine context of NAFTA. In contrast to econometrical approaches finat focus naturally on statistical significance, fine computable general equilibrium (CGE) approach allows a calculation of absolute levels of importance. 1.6.2. Inclusion of Environmental Extemality The empirical literature focuses on fine impact of pollution abatement on trade specialization. Remarkably, it neglects fine extemality aspect of pollution. Potentially, fine 46 integation of extemalities into fine analysis can significanfiy effect results. Resource depletion deprives a country of fine opportunity to develop ofiner industries such as tourism, which are potentially big foreign-exchange earners. Pollution may harm people and materials or deter industries from locating in a country. There exists only a small body of descriptive literature finat emphasizes fine negative aspects of trade liberalization itself. This orrnission stems fiom fine fineory of fine second best that fine removal of trade distortions can lead to a worsening of a courntry's situation-- environmentally or economically--if ofiner distortions still exist. In an autarkic state it may not be consequential finat a natural resource like tropical wood is underpriced. An opening of fine borders for exports worsens fine effect of fine distortion and leads to environmental deterioration. " While the argument itself is straightforward, its analytical and empirical examination is made difficult by fine complexity of fine technical and economic relationships and fine ofien considerable time finat elapses between fine emission and fine time finat fine full damage occurs. Even if fine country gains an advantage in fine short-term, a policy-induced comparative advantage in resource-intensive sectors disappears as fine resource depletes. An analytical " There are many examples of this sort. See for example Arden-Clarke (1992a). Sorrne ecological econonnists take the thought even filrther and argue that trade generally should be minimized (Morris 1990; Daly 1993; Daly and Cobb 1989). The envirorunental argument these authors make- -there are other etlnical considerations not relevant for this paper—is that trade always entails transportation and consequently energy consumption, with all its unwanted side efl‘ects of resource depletion, pollution, etc. More trade therefore leads to environmental deterioration. Cross-hauling of near identical goods across borders can be readily accepted as an example of this point. Brande and Krugrnan (1983) formulate a model where the waste of resources involved in the reciprocal shipping of identical goods may outweigh the benefit of increased competition. It is, however, questionable, whether finis should be taken as an argument against trade itself. The real problem lies obviously in fine underpricing of fine environmental resources. If fine "correct" price for energy issohigbtlnattradewouldfallasaconsequenceofhiglnertransportationcosts,thereisstilllittle economic argument for the imposition of trade barriers after fire price change. 47 integration of exterrnality may reveal finat lax environmental regulations lead to a deterioration of a. country's trade position, as a country’s non-polluting export sector declines urnder fine burden of fine ofiner sector‘s pollution. The static CGE model of firis paper addresses fine problem by integating fine impact of pollution on healfin into fine analysis. This integration allows an analysis of fine welfare impact of policy changes when economic gowfin and pollution move in opposite direction Furfinermore, it enables to assess fine importance of fine extemality on fine industrial structure. 1.6.3. Endogenous Treatment of Pollution Factors Bofin fineoretical and empirical studies on trade and environment assume factor endowments and institutions to be constant. In combination wifin fine poverty attraction hypofinesis, finese assumptions result in an easy detenninacy of fine direction of trade-induced change: Trade is bad for environment because it moves dirty industries to places where regulatory enforcement is weak (even finough fine enforcement itself may not be fine driver). However, it is well established that regulation stringency increases wifin ecornonnic development. The cererl‘s paribus assumption for regulatory stringency is finerefore not legitimate, insofar as trade promotes development. In many cases, fine pollution result of fine poverty attraction hypofinesis reverts, if regulation-setting is treated analytically as an endogenous process. As a complement, this paper finerefore formulates a “institutional optinnism hypofinesis”: fine relocation of industries cannot be separated fiom fire creation of wealfin, which again is a key determinant of a country’s regulatory stringency. Since free trade is finerefore closely associated wifin fine application of pollution standards, it will generally lead to environmental improvements, even if a courntry is attractive for pollution-intensive sectors. The institutional optimism hypofinesis will 48 be developed formally in Chapter 2. This hypofinesis will also be empirically analyzed in fine CGE model. 49 CHAPTER2 THE INSTITUTIONAL OPTIMISM HYPOTHESIS The main body of empirical and fineoretical literature takes fine environmental regulation level as externally given The present chapter will show fine importance of finis assumption and argue that it systematically leads to a rrnisjudgment of the environmental consequences of trade liberalization. A first section first develop fine economic and political mecharnisms justifying an endogenous treatment of regulation levels in fine analysis. Section two develops fine ideas in a fineoretical Heckscher-Ohlin type model finat traces fine consequences of such an endogenous treatment. A finird section interprets fine results and formulates fine irnstitutional optimism hypofinesis. A fourth section will describe a disaggregation procedure for an empirical examination of fine hypofinesis. 2.1. Economic Development as Explanation of Environmental Stringency 2.1.1. Development and Production Patterns Trade contributes to fine economic development of a country. The empirical evidence of an environmental Kuznnets curve points to fine fact finat economic development and pollution do not form a linear relationship. The decomposition of environmental effects serves to disentarngle wlnat might explain fine relationship. The scale effect in isolation would have suggested finat economic development entails a straightforward increase in emission levels. Evidenfiy, finerefore during fine different stages of economic growfin, finere must be a distinct pattern finat influences fine two ofiner important effects identified by Grossman and Krueger (1992), fine composition efl‘ect and fine technology effect. These will be addressed in turn. The stylized facts of fine econonnic development process are presented graphically in Figure 2-1. 50 machete: Poor and medium income countries tend to have a high share of dirty sectors. (Figure 2- 1, parnel A). The argument presented here focuses on four factors finat explain why poor countries might be prone to having dirty industries. First, poor countries tend to have a lnigh demand for basic production which tends to be dirty, bofin for final consumption goods, as well as for investment. Consumption in wealfinier countries tends to be more service oriented Secornd, labor endowment in poor country tends to consist of a pool of unskilled labor. This endowment gives fine country a comparative advantage in heavy industrial or agricultural production. Third, poor countries are capital poor. It is not clear whether finis poverty should move fine sectoral composition of the industry. towards clean or dirty sector. However, it contributes to pollution-intensive production technology, as will be elaborated below. Fourfin, irn poor countries resource extraction tends to have a relatively high share in natiornal production All finese factor give a comparative advantage to pollution-intensive industries irn poor countries. If such countries open to trade, finis comparative advantage nnight be reinforced In essence, finis conclusion is a restatement of fine poverty attraction hypofinesis. As a country gets richer, fine relative advantage nnight change, and fine relative pollution intensity would decrease. In itself, fine composition efi‘ect might finerefore explain part of fine relative greening of richer connrntries. However, it could not explain an absolute drop in pollution levels for rich countries, because structural change is normally not accompanied by an absolute decline but a relative decline of certain sectors (Figure 2-1, panel B). 51 Figure 2-1. Decomposition of the environmental Kuzrnets curve A. Structural change Polution B. Unadjusted pollution curve GDP Unfit uni-ions C. Institutional and technical change GDP Polution D. Environmental Kuznets curve GDP 52 Icahnalansflest Production technology in poor countries is also largely a fimctiorn of resource endowment, notably fine lack of capital. Physical capital is often of an old vintage. Old vintage capital stock is likely to be more polluting finan newer equipment Retrofitting is generally expensive. Increased wealfin and, hence, capital stock tends to reduce emissions first, because environmental improvements are linked to fine replacement of fine capital stock. Second, because low levels of capital endowment make environmental investments expensive in foregone production. F irnally, new and environmentally friendly technologies are often capital irntensive. This intensity is due especially to fine fact that production processes are mosfiy developed. by rich countries for fire need of rich countries. Wifin increased capitalization of productiorn, fine likelilnood increases finat fine technology has been developed by fine first world, arnd finerefore tends to be environmentally cleaner. finan fine existing technology of fine developing country. Irncreased capitalization of production may finerefore lead direcfiy to lower pollution per nnrnit of production, alfinough finere exist counter-examples. Greener production technology is certainly fine crucial reason why wealfinier countries can be cleaner countries. However, it leaves fine question why finey actually are cleaner. The inverted U-relationship of pollution appears to indicate an increasing importance of fine teclnnology efl’ect from a certain income level onwards. (Figure 2-1, last two panels) This result canbeexplainedonlybyalookatfine institutional aspectofregulation settingfinatwillbe discussed more extensively. 2.1.2. Development and Institutions Pollution control requires fine existence of functioning regulatory institutiorns. The endsternce of finese irnstitutions is intimately tied to a country’s wealfin, because fine demand for 53 environmental quality is higlnly income elastic. (Esty 1994). Clean environment is a rnorrnal good Its efi‘ective demand rises wifin fine level of income. For very poor people, fine basic corncern is to earn a livelihood for finemselves and fineir families. In such a situatiorn, fine concern for fine environment tends is not expressed in fine market and fine political processes. As a courntry gets richer and its population is increasingly able to bear a reduction in fineir disposable income, fine demand for environmental service increases. If fine political process permits it, environmental regulations will become more stringent in such a case. Furfinemnore, a clear link can be established between fine income and education level of fine country and fine level of public accountability of fine administration (Hettige et al 1996, 1997).12 The difference in institutional capacity between poor and rich courntries is often commented on (Chichilrnisky 1994; O’Connor 1994). Dasgupta et al. (1995) find empirically that fine amount of regulation increases steadily with fine gowfin of per capita incomes. There are several arguments finat support a behavioral assumption of finis type. Forenost, increased wealfin (approximated by fine capital intensity) decreases fire willingness to tolerate pollution The desire for stricter standards may be fine direct result of increased income itself, since a clean environment is somefinirng ofa luxury good , or may be caused indirecfiy finrougln higher general education finat usually correlates wifin increased wealfin. Irnasmuch as environmental awareness and preferences are closely related to people's educational levels, higlner income will result in stricter pollution standards. This argument will be elaborated furfiner below. ‘2 Sclden and Song (1994) provide similar arguments. 54 A transactions-cost efi‘ect complements fine income effect While fine irncome efi‘ect is denarnd driven and relies on a positive income elasticity of a clean environment, fine transactions-cost efi‘ect results from changes on fine production side. Naturally, enterprises have an incentive to cheat on environmental regulations, if finere is litfie likeliness in getting caught Mornitoring is expensive, however, and almost certainly involves econonnies of scale. If an ecornomy sets aside a certain percentage of its income for regulatory enforcement, its eficiency is bound to rise as fine value of production irncreases. There are considerable dificulties in statistically verifying finis transactions-cost hypofinesis. However, fine capability of a state to raise tax revenues may serve as a proxy for its ability to enforce regulations in general. Clearly, finere is a trend for fine share, ifnot fine size, ofa country's irnforrnal economy to fall as its per- capita income rises. This analogy lends some plausibility to fine argument finat an increased capital/labor ratio could result in a higher regulatory standard, even if fine demand for environmental quality is completely income inelastic. Chiclnilrnisky (1994) stresses fine importance of property rights in determining fine relative abundance of a country in natural resources ill a Norfin-Soufin trade model. Chiclnilnisky's discussion shows that property rights by finemselves can detemnine a country's resource aburndance. As fine strengfin of fine property rights is correlated to fine income level of a country, fine argument made by Chiclnilrrisky can be seen as a variation of fine transactions-cost argmnent made above. Despite fineir seemingly similar implicatiorns, fine income and fine transactions-cost argument difi‘er qualitatively. The former assumes finat fine regulatory policies are optimal for a given income level, while fine latter assumes fine existence of distortions. Iffinere exists only an income effect, finere is no systematic change in fine extemality costs, because fine marginal costs 55 of pollution rise at fine same time finat pollution levels decline. For fine transactions-cost case, an increase in capital endowment reduces fine extemality, which is fine gap between marginal benefits of production and marginal costs of pollution. (Since fine model presented here does not include any extemality effects, a distinction is not made in fine model.) The relationship between income and regulatory stringency conforms also wifin fine more sophisticated approach used in fine political science literature. One can separate fine relationslnip between income and environmental regulations into two components: preference formatiorn arnd fine translation of preferences into actual policies. It is argued here finat increased wealfin and socioeconomic development is a contributing factor to bofin a value system finat assigns irncreased importance to fine environment, as well as to more democratic political institutions that react to finese preferences. The conditions for fine development of democratic structures are among fine oldest topies studied by political scientists. Explanatory models stress fine importance of cultural or of socioeconomic factors (Arat 1988, p.21). For instance, Inglelnard (1990) describes how economic development is accompanied by a complex change in fine socioecornonnic and political system. He identifies several levels at which political changes take place. First, a certain level of economic and technological development is a necessary conditiorn for fine increased importance of post-materialistic values, because it liberates people fiom concern about basic economic security. Essentially, finis requirement means finat people move up fine Maslow pyramid of needs as more basic wants are satisfied Secondly, finis movement is reinforced finrough rising levels of education of fine general population. These first two factors were already identified earlier. A finird factor influencing values is what Inglelnard calls distinctive cohort experiences. The history and culture of a country are important factors, since 56 finey shape fine fininking of a cohort in fineir formative years. Socioeconomic clnange usually has litfie efl‘ect on fine values of cohorts whose way of fininking is set, but irnfluences mainly fine yournger generations. Value change finerefore is usually associated wifin generatiornal change. A changing set of values would, however, be incornsequential if no political skills exist finat trarnslate fine values into politics. These skills are shaped finrough experiences arnd learning-by- doing of fine colnort, and are furfinered finrough fine expansion of mass media, which enlarge fine pool of people who have access to information on fine political process. The combined changes in values and skills induced by economic progress exert pressure finat makes environmental issues more relevant, and strengfinerns fine channels of polifical cornflict finat will translate finis pressure into practical politics, or rrnore corncretely into stricter environmental regulation. Furfiner factors omitted by Inglehard, such as income distribution are likely to work in fine same direction. There exists empirical evidence to support fine argument For example, Dahl (1971) and Arat (1988) establish a positive relationship between ecornomic variables and political freedom and democracy. One can establish from fine accumulated economic and political evidence a direct lirnk between irncreased income and stronger institutions to protect fine environment A simplified equation (e. g. as an income elasticity of ennission standards) can finerefore be direcfiy used irn economic modeling. Such an analytical representation will be central to fine filrfiner argument of finis paper. However, a few interpretative caveats apply to such a simplified equation. Most irnportanfiy, fine described socio-political changes do not occur wifin necessity or irnstantaneously. It would not difficult to find various reasons and cases finat would contradict 57 such an short-term interpretation of fine relationship. 13 However, an income-elasticity of regulation exists as a long-term trend wifin an interpretation finat is similar to finat of a long-term equilibrium of an economy: a useful simplification of fine real world In a comparative static equilibrium analysis it can be simply understood as marking fine pressure on fine economy finat is irnduced by a certain set of policy changes. Furfinennore, a comparative static analysis leaves out fine irnportarnt questiorns of fine trarnsitiorn process to fine new equilibrium. Conceivably, an environmental resource could be irretrievably lost in fine transition period The movement to a difi'erent equilibrium nniglnt therefore be unattainable because, in fine interirrr, fine very conditions for fine existence of fine ofiner equilibrium are destroyed. Finally, for purposes of modeling, a smoofin function serves as approximation of fine process towards stricter regulations. By contrast in real life, political and regulatory change often takes place in a discrete rafiner than a continuous fashion. However, it is not possible, ex ante to know exacfiy where, if at all, finere might be finresholds above which certain changes take place. 2.1.3. Trade and Environmental Regulation It is clear from fine previous discussion finat environmental standards cannot simply be taken as given On fine one hand trade nnight improve environmental performance direcfiy. Trade itself, as opposed to autarky, increases fine stock of krnowledge by giving a courntry ‘3 One may think of fine example of the old Soviet Union as a state for which nnost socioeconomic indicators would suggestfineexistenceofahighdcgreeofdenocrafizationandconcemfortbe environnnent, but where bofin are conspicuously absent. 58 access to foreign innovations and knowledge (Grossman and Helpman 1995). Trade openness itself might finerefore be associated wifin a cleaner industrial base. Lucas at al. (1992) derived finat open economies show a significantly lesser growfin in pollution levels than closed econorrnies. Birdsall and Wheeler's (1992) analysis of fine situation in Latin America, shows finat openness for trade leads to a lower level of environmental degradation, since trade involves a transfer of technology. Wheeler and Martin (1992) present anecdotal evidence finat, in fine case of the paper and pulp industry in Latin America, investrnnent by foreign firms appears to be followed by fine import of pollution-control technology as well as industrial country pollution standards. Openness of fine economy is a major factor for fine adoption of pollution-saving technology, because it removes existing distortions. By contrast, fine aufinors' find no independent efl‘ect of a country's development level on fine adoption of clean tedunology. However, fine evidence on outward orientation and decreasing pollution-intensity has been questioned by Rock (1996). As a more political component of fine direct efl‘ect of trade on regulation, one might also add fine political pressure from trading partners, for instance, in fine context of NAFI' A. Potentially as important as fine efi‘ect of trade liberalization of fine poorer country's economic structure may be fine deregulation of its financial markets. In fine context of NAFTA, some studies assume finat it would reduce fine risk prennium on Mexican capital rates by 1 percentage point (CBC 1992). To finis one would need to add fine effect of increased eficiency in financial services due to U.S. competition and fine inflow of U.S. capital. Mexican investment is likely to increase as a consequence, which by itself may lead to increased or decreased pollutiorn, depending on fine type of investment finat is induced In general, however, a lower discount rate shifts fine trade-off between resource conservation and depletion irn favor 59 of a lower rate of exploitation. The interest rate efi‘ect may thus work as a factor finat pushes Mexico irnto becoming a cleaner country. Anofiner line of argument follows directly from fine discussion of fine previous section and takes fine link between wealfin and institutions as a starting point. There is no fineoretical or empirical trade literature finat treats environmental regulatiorn directly as a function of wealfin However, Chichilnisky (1994) makes environmental stringency endogenous to fine analysis through a property-rights determined supply function. She assumes fine property-rights situation in fine Norfin to be well defined, so finat here fine supply curve of fine natural resource follows fine social optimum. In fine Soufin, fine lack of enforcement leads to a more outward- lying private supply curve, which does not consider extemalities. In a general-equilibrium framework, she derives finat fine supply curve for fine natural resource can be downward- sloping. The model assumes finat fine private suppliers of fine resource have no alternative employment finan to bring fineir labor into fine production of fine resource, while finey consurnne a second good which finey purchase fionn fineir revenues. Under finese assumptions, their optimal allocation problem is one between consumption of fine good and leisure time. When fine price of fine resource falls, two effects occur. The first is fine substitution efi‘ect: Work decreases as fine reward for working declines. The second is fine income effect: As wages fall low enough, nnore efi‘ort needs to be applied to earn fine subsistence income. In finis case, resource exploitation will increase as fine terms of trade turn against fine resource. Raising fine capital intensity will increase fine factor reward for resource exploitation and may finerefore lead to a decreased level of exploitation, if fine economy operates on fine backward-bending part of fine environmental supply curve. Raising a tax on fine exploitation of 60 fine resource, on fine ofiner hand, could produce an unintended rise in environmental destruction, increase fine comparative resource abundance of fine Soufin, and lead to exports of resource— intensive goods. The property rights determined resource abundance is finerefore similar in result as fine wealfin determined regulation setting. Dome and Schulze (1996) provide anofiner attempt to fine aufinor to internalize fine pollution stringency level into fine trade analysis. In many respects fineir fineoretical model which is also applied to fine NAFI‘ A situation parallels fine ideas finat will be developed in this elmpter. However, fire Bommer-Schulze political paradigm is substantially different fiorn fine one that will be developed further below. Following Stigler’s (1971) and Peltzman’s (1976) fineory of regulation, in fine Bommer-Schulze model, fine administration sets environmental standards to maximize a political support function composed of net exporting sectors, net importing sectors, workers and environmentalists. As trade liberalization changes fine relative well-being of finese four groups, environmental policies need to counterbalance fine negative efi‘ects on fine losing groups. Bommer and Schulze establish that United States exports are relatively more pollution- intensive finan imports. Taking fine United States as a vantagepoint, finey argue that trade liberalization wifin Mexico puts exporters and labor on fine winning side, while importers arnd environmental interests sufi‘er. They finen argue finat finis constellation automatically puts pressure on fine administration to increase fine stringency of environmental legislation, which serves fine interests of fine two losing actors. Environmental interests are helped for obvious reasons; importers are helped because finey are not pollution intensive and could finus improve fineir relative position The aufinors claim finat fine environmental side agreements of NAFTA are evidence of finis hypofinesis. 61 However, several core assumptions of fine Bommer-Schulze hypofinesis are inaccurate. Irrnportanfiy, while it may be correct finat fine United States exporting industries are relatively pollution-intensive compared to importing industries, finis relationship is unlikely to be true for actual embodied pollution, because US regulations are more stringent finan finose in fine rest of fine world (see discussion in Chapter 4). The NAFTA-environment discussion in fine US was dominated by fear finat polluting industry would migrate to Mexico due to fineir lower environmental standards (fine industrial flight hypofinesis in our terms). The assumption finat trade is perceived by environmentalists as pollution-increasing is certainly correct However, fine line of argument was not that pollution would increase in fine US but in Mexico. Home and Schulze finerefore misjudge fine US debate on Mexico as a pollution haven and fine possible erosion of US environmental standards as a consequence. As a result, fine NAFTA environmental side agreements were not directed at manufacturers in fine US as implied by fine aufinors, but at manufacturers in Mexico. Furfilermore, while it may be correct finat in fine long-nln US workers might benefit from a trade agreement, finis fact does not translate politically into fine direction pointed out by Home and Schulze, because Labor perceived itself as a loser, not a winner of NAFTA Possible reasons for this may be the resulting insecurity of structural change, the fact finat (losing) incumbents are better organized finan fine diffuse and uncertain winners of trade liberalization, or simply fine fact that certain segments wifinin labor, like fine unskilled, might lose while ofiners, like fine university trained, might gain. Therefore, fine internalization approach of our paper follows a difi‘erent. route of intemalizatiorn, using fine income level as fine factor in determining stringency in environmental regulation. 62 2.2 Trade Model with Endogenous Environmental Regulation This section develops fine arguments of fine previous section in an analytical model. The mafinematically disinclined reader might move on to section 2.3. wifinout loss in fine argument. 2.2.1. The Standard Model Following fine standard assumptions of trade modeling, a Heckscher-Ohlin world is assumed wifin two traded goods X and Y. The home country is small and takes fine price levels as really extemally given. The price of good Y is used as denominator for all prices. P denotes fine costs of a unit of X in units of Y, similarly, w and r denote fine wage rate and fine return on capital. We assume finat all parameters are wifinin a range finat prohibits a complete specialization of fine country. The imported good Y is produced following a Cobb-Douglas function finat uses capital (K) and labor (L) as inputs. For fine production of the export good X an additional environmental input (E) is needed, according to a fine production function: 2.1 X =E'L‘K‘ S X X where s,A,x>0, e+l+x=1.1hisequafionmeansfinatfineproducfiornfmcfionislinearly inmgenlsinitshnpmwluchisfinesmndmdassumpfiminHecksdne-Ohhnnndes.Irnfine absmceofamgfiafietfinepmducemwoulduseaninfimemmmnoffineenvirmmemlinputE.In ordetolimitfineuseoffineenvironmentalinput,itisnowassumedfinatthegovenmentiswillingto accept pollution only ifit produces a certain level of output Mafilematically, finis msumption is 63 etpressedasfineconditionfinatfinemarginalproductivityofenvironmenthastobeatleast lt“'l'his first-order condition for the producers ochan then be written as: 2.2 p = cE"’L;K; Solving finis for E produces I a I: .3.. _~_ 2.3 X = - L1“ K3" In Iffine factor reward is not taxed away, but stays wifin fine producers of good X, we can substitute equation 2.3 back into fine production function (equation 2.1) and obtain: a 1%; _£_ _~_ 2.. x = H L}:~K,‘*~ In It can be easily seen finat fine production flmction of X wifin endogenous E is linearly honnogernous in K and L. To avoid notational clutter, let us rewrite fine production function as: I 2.5 X = [i] L;K;'°‘ p wherea= ’1 landflz a = ‘ .crmarksfineadjustednewfactorshareoflabor, 1+}: 1+): I-e whfleficmbeintepreedasfinereafiwineeaseinfineremnoffinemn-ewimnemlinputsthat canbeascribedtofineenvimnmentIfeisO.25,finenfineretunnstolaborandcapitalareaugnented byonefinirdltcanbeseenfinatpollufiornisasimplelinearfimcfionofX “ This approach has been used by McGuire 1982. 2.6 E: X f. ,u The environmental intensity is related inversely to fine minimum marginal productivity, but rises wifin file factor share 8 of fine environmental input. The production of Y is assumed to produce no environmental extemalities. Its production function is 2.7 . Y = L: Kfi'“ The labor intensity onis 6times finat ofgoodX. A value for fismallerfinan l mearns that polluting good is also relatively labor intensive, which would approximate fine relative position of fine poorer country. From finese assumptions, we can derive fine first-order conditions fl [-0 1““ K p LJr Ly and 2.9 r = p(1— 43111;: J = (1- M{%]" The capital-labor ratio is a function of fine wage-profit ratio. K 2.10 33: “ K*=—5‘3——’- r I-aL, 1-6a Ly Thiscanbetransformedinto _ K K 2.11 1("=—‘5 6“-—’=¢—i L, 1-6a Ly Ly 65 6+6a where 50 = 1+6a marksfinedifl‘eenceinfinecapital/laborratios.Iinsrelafivelymore labor intensive than Y, then 6<1,and l/I<1. Substitutiorn ofequatiorn 2.9 into 2.11 yields equatian 2.12. .V 1 5 7—5. - T -n ‘" 2.12 Ky :(g) ’ l (i) ‘ ¢a(J-1)L [I Iffine total stock of labor and capital is limited by the equations 2.13a K = K" +Ky 2Bb L=g+g fine model is solvable and fine following results are obtained: 41-54) I I a(a—i) 2.14a L =—‘/’— -—L+ K‘— ¢‘(""K y 1_¢ all! I I tin-5) i 2.141) K =-—1——|:_[p£’] ¢a(l-J)K ¢ I I m -(l—a) 2.14c L =—1—[L-[fl;] ¢“""K I .71?) LL 2.14d Kx=1¢¢[[p5’) ¢a(l-J)L_K Furfiner 66 "‘ (14.x: ) I a(l—:) ‘° 2.15a w=§a[pE ]_ ¢ 4") r(l-e) 2.15b r = (14%”, )Hto (“’1 6p” and 1 6, fig” l-2oa+u’: ‘r’ ;—_ 311;.) 2.16a Y=——— - 13— ¢ “(”5 L+ p 36 H K I-gb 6):” 6,11” l-ad -d 5’ a(,_ 3) (I- Xm-a) , p ,_ 3 _—___5(1-.) 2.16b )(=—’—-1 [F J— p <’ ‘1 L— [1" ] ¢ 1-. K 1-¢P 5;: 6;: These equations reproduce fine standard Heckscher-Ohlin results. Equation 2.161) for instance reveals finat an increase in fine capital stock lowers fine output of X, if X is relatively labor-intensive, i.e. 6 is smaller than 1. This is fine Rybczynski fineorem. Similarly, it can be verified that fine Stolper-Samuelson fineorem holds in fine model. If fine relative price of X increases, fine relative wage rate will rise, if labor is fine factor finat is used intensively irn fine production of X. 67 Figure 2-2. Trade liberalization with constant environmental regulations Include... ' M‘ ¥ Clean good Since fine country is assumed to have a comparative advantage in fine production of X, trade liberalization would result in an increase in its relative price. A higher P results in an increased production of X for fine export market, while fine production of Y drops and is partially replaced finrough imports. In Figure 2-2, production moves from fine autarky production poirnt A on fine production possibility frontier to point B under open trade. Consumption now takes place at point B. The improved terms of trade for file polluting sector result in an increased production. Because resource use is a simple multiple of fine production of X as defined by equation 2.5, pollution will increase in parallel. The model presents fine standard arguments of fine consequences of trade liberalization For a courntry witln low pollution standards, trade liberalization leads to an increased production of fine pollution intensive good and, consequently, to an environmental deterioration in fine home conmtry. Trade liberalization can potentially be welfare reducing, if fine increased consumption 68 in fine country, which moves fiom A in Figure 2-2 to B, does not compensate for fine increased pollution finat fine population now suffers. A low ennissions standard it serves as a substitute for a high price level P and exacerbates fine situation. In graphical terms, lax pollution requirements move fine production possibility frontier inward. 2.2.2. The Modified Model Several mechanisms could make it , which denotes fine trade-off between production and environment finat fine population is willing to accept, model endogenous. In finis paper, we propose a dependence of p on fine capital-labor ratio of X according to fine functional form: 2.17 p=[f’) This means fine required marginal productivity of T increases exponentially wifin fine capital intensity. This is a useful proxy for what would more precisely be represented as an income elasticity of regulation. However, setting I) as a function of U would extremely complicate fine analysis wifinout adding anyfining to fine argument developed here. Wifin finese preliminaries, fine model can now be solved. Using fine equation I _— [-05 2.18 —K‘= pr” “(l-”WM L dp’ X and substituting equation 2.17) yields file following formula for p: q ‘ C(I-Jyrfi ”(I‘d) “(’3‘ J— 69 Ifwe substitute equation 2.19 irnto equations 2.14 and 2.16 of fine previous chapter, fine results change into 2.20a F «(I-6w H‘ 2.2% K, = 7—1—[-[p 6‘ J p 4H“ L +K 1 pa” «(I-51M: (’ ""3) 2.20c L1: =—- L-[ J (’ "WK 1- 6 ¢ p 5.! 41.15),” 7’1",— 2.20d K, = ¢°"‘WL_K 1- 511 6 and 1 5.! fig "245*‘425MH 8, fl; «HI-re!) 2.21a r =_ _ P ¢——«u-w L, P ¢WK 1-¢ 6 [’4'”! -a-rfl , , —a(l-J)+¢ I-e-erU-r) I m -.-.,g 2.21b X: e I" p “(NH L- .125— W 1-. eK 1 - ¢ 6 6 The behavior of pollution is now 2.22 l-¢-v(l-fi) -a-r(l+;) ‘¢"1(I*”d) 1+! I “(1")”, l-c-r,+.r(l-a+r,) , “(14)”, E: a [pa ¢ «(l-5)"! L- P; ¢ 41-3)»; K 1-¢ a 70 Ifnisequalto0,noincome efi‘ectexistsandfileoutcomeisidenticaltofineprevious results from equations 2.14 and 2.15. However, as 17 increases, fine model results change qualitatively. There exist finree value ranges for fine pollution elasticity. If r) is low, fine standard result Occurs: An increase in fine price of fine polluting good increases bofin fine output and fine pollution level. If n is at a medium level, X will be stricfiy increasing, but fine pollution level willstarttodropbeyondacertainlevel,asfineincreaseinfineoutputoffinepollutinggoodis overcompensated finrough increasingly stricter regulations. At high levels of n, finally, bofin fine productiorn of X and fine level of pollution begin to fall beyond a certain level. These results are summarized in Table 2.1. Figure 2-3: Trade liberalization with endogenous environmental regulation setting Pelhthggeed Clea-good 71 Table 2-1: Summary of Model Results Rangeofq XasfunctionofP EasflmctionofP < 1 - a Increasing Irncreasing I] 1 + fl 1 - a 1 - 0. Increasing Inverted U l + B B 1_-_(_1_ < 7l Inverted U Inverted U B The model demonstrates how fine existence of an income effect can fundamentally alter fine environmental efi‘ect of trade liberalization. Trade liberalization can potentially reduce fine pollution even in fine country wifin a comparative advantage in fine pollution-intensive good Figure 2-3 depicts fine mechanism graphically: A again denotes fine production and consumption level in fine state of autarky. It is fine tangency point of fine indifference curve nmde fine pollution constraint level A, which reflects fine price level under autarky (shovwn as fine dotted line). Wifin constant regulations, consumption would move to point B and consumption to point E. However, filese points are not compatible wifin fine efl‘ect finat fine price level has on fine stringency of fine pollution standards. Since it increases as a result of trade opening, fine production frontier moves inward (fine solid line). This means finat production moves now to point F while consumption takes place at point G. Therefore, an unadjusted calculatidn of fine trade efi‘ect will overestimate file increase in fine polluting good Even more so will it overestimate fine induced pollution effect. 2.3. The Institutional Optimism Hypothesis 2.3.1. Formulation of the Hypothesis For a country finat has a comparative advantage in pollution-intensive industries, fine impact of- trade liberalizatiorn on pollution is a priori ambivalent. One can identify two efl‘ects 72 working in opposite directions. First, fine country will specialize in fine pollution intensive industry, which results bofin in an increased scale of fine economy and in an altered composition Thisresultisatfineheartoffinefiaditional hypofinesis and, inannodifiedfornnoffinepoverty attraction hypofilesis. A second often-neglected effect of trade is on fine environmental institutions finrough wealfin creation. Section 2.1. discussed fine mechanisms finrough which trade liberalization tends to strengfinen fine functioning of regulatory institutions. Section 2.2 presented an analytical model finat discusses fine interaction of fine specialization and regulation effects of trade. Which one of fine two dominates, is an empirical question. Its answer is at fine heart of fine trade and environment debate. It can be formulated as a finird big empirical hypofinesis on trade and environment, fine institutional optimism hypofilesis. Since free trade is closely associated wifin fine application of pollution standards (mainly finrough wealfin creation), it will generally lead to environmental improvements, even if a country is attractive for pollution-intensive sectors. On fine empirical answer to fine hypofinesis ultimately hinges fine question whefiner trade as such is good or bad for fine environment Indirectly, it is also of fundamental importance concerning fine strategy environmental interests should pursue vis-a-vis trade issues. In moving finis issue forward, fine remainder of this section will address fine question what enpirical evidence might corroborate fine institutional optinnism hypofinesis. Section 2.4. will develop some mefinodological preliminaries. 2.3.2. Empirical Evidence There is no empirical evidence that tests fine institutional optimism hypofinesis direcfiy. A full econometric analysis of the issue would require the statistically difficult separation at is two counteracting efl‘ects. Even fine separate analysis of file specialization and fine institutiornal 73 efi‘ect is lacking. In fine context of industrial flight hypofinesis, fine previous chapter showed finat few of fine regressions of trade specialization on explanatory variables yielded statistically significant results. On fine impact of wealfin on regulatory stringency, fine discussion above pointed to substantive anecdotal evidence. Difiiculties of having a good yardstick for environmental stringency is a major obstacle to a more detailed statistical analysis. Mucln analysis is finerefore based on measuring pollution levels irnstead of environmental regulation, for irnstance fine literature on fine environmental Kuznets curve. Neverfineless, fine environmental Kumets curve can be taken as indirect evidence for fine institutional optinnism hypofinesis. It is clear on fine one hand, finat fine curve is also compatible wifin ofiner explarnatory models, such as fine standard pafin of economic development and fine associated changes in economic composition. In decomposing fine pollution-income efi‘ect, Lucas et al. (1992) have found supporting evidence for finis hypofilesis finat pollution reduction is due mainly to a composition efl‘ect. High pollution may thus be just a fnmction of early industrialization, which relies heavily on mineral processing and ofiner relatively dirty industry, while fine income efl‘ect on regulations may be of only secondary importance. On fine ofine hand, it cannot be excluded finat fine changing industrial structure is not to some extent caused by changes in environmental legislation. However, it is unlikely finat fine composition efi‘ect alone would sufice to generate a downward trend in absolute pollution levels. Principally, only fine regulation efi‘ect could achieve finis alone. However, this effect would need to be fairly high. to compensate bofin for scale and composition effect. If fine composition effect were zero, fine regulation efl‘ect would have to be larger finan one. The analytical model in fine previous section shows finat fine introduction of a regulation efi‘ect can reproduce fine inverted U-shape. However, fine analytical 74 result relies not just on fine regulation effect, but also on fine composition efl‘ect (filrough a lower output of fine polluting good) and fine scale effect (low overall output). The dificulty in interpreting fine results of fine environmental Kuznets curve is finat fine analysis is results-based. The statistical relationship between income and pollution need not imply a causal relationship. This means it considers fine development of environmental indicators wifinout fine decomposing whefiner it is due to changing econonnic compositiorn, more stringent regulation or technical progress. A separate problem in finis context is finat not only might higher income lead to stricter regulation but also environmental regulations determine fine potential for economic growfin. On fine one hand, strict regulations nnight make an area unattractive for a number of enterprises. On fine ofiler hand, a clean environment and low extemalifies might make fine area rrnore attractive for ofiner sectors. To answer finis question, it is necessary to statistically separate fine bi-directional causal relationship between income and regulation. This is inherently impossible to do wifin simple cross-country data sets, but time-series data are necessary. Alfinougln he does not analyze exactly file question at hand, fine study by Schimmelpfennig (1992) is worfin noticing as a first attempt at statistically separating fine bi-directional relationship between income and pollution levels. Using time-series county data of fine U.S., he finds finat an increase in the level of income causes a higher level of pollution, wlnile finere is some, finough not significant, evidence finat lower pollution improves economic productivity. While cross-country studies are often a means of necessity, because finere exist few reliable time series on pollution data, finey do not necessarily allow fine conclusion finat fine functional relatiornslnips established here pertain also in a time pafin. 75 2.4. An Illustrative Application of the Institutional Optimism Hypothesis: A decomposition procedure 2.4.1. Introduction and Case Description The discussion of fine previous section shows finat fine empirical information on fine ove'all pollution level of a country does not sufice to provide strong evidence about fire causes of fine overall effect Much less is finere any hint m to how trade might influence fine result, because of the interplay of scale, composition and regulation effect More finan fine industrial flight arnd fine poverty attraction hypofinesis, fine institutional optimism requires a disaggregation of file overall pollution impact into components. This section will develop such decomposition wifin an illustrative example. We consider a simple Ricardian case of trade liberalization. The example reflects very closely fine mechanisms at work in a CGE model, it also illustrates fine taxonomy finat will be used in fine rest offine text. Table 2.2 lists outputs, inputs, consumption, and emissions for two countries A and B, where A is more eficient at producing X, while B is better at producing Y. For illustrative purposes we assume a Cobb«Douglas utility function wifin equal weights for bofin goods. Table 2.2: The effect of trade on two fictive economies Scenario Region Output Consumption Emissions Welfare X Y X Y X Y Total 0. Autarky Country A 20 10 20 10 40 30 70 14.1 (Emission fac- Country B 10 20 10 20 20 60 80 14.1 tor x=2;y=3) World 30 3O 30 30 60 90 150 914.1 1. Trade Country A 20 10 15 15 40 30 7O 15 without produc- Country B 10 20 15 15 20 60 80 15 tion changes World 30 3O 30 30 60 90 150 $15 2. Trade with Country A 40 - 20 2O 8O - 80 20 production Country B - 4O 20 20 - 120 120 20 changes World 40 40 40 40 80 120 200 $20 3. Regulations: Country A 36 - 18 18 S4 - 54 18 Emissions -25% Country B - 36 18 18 - 81 81 18 Output -10%; World 36 36 36 36 54 81 135 018 Note: Utility U - x °-‘ Y °-‘. This excludes any extemalities 76 In fine autarky case bofin countries consume fineir output in a ratio of 2 to 1 depending on fine relative advantage. They achieve a utility level of 14.1, while pollution lies at 70 arid 80 units, respectively. The aspect of trade liberalization can now be disaggregated into three steps. W In finis case, fine only adjustment would take place irn fine consumption pattern. This increases welfare to a level of 15, but does not use a country’s comparative advantage. It has no consequence for pollution. This step shows fine barter efi'ect of trade. However, furfiner below, fine broade term allocation efi‘ect is used, which includes two further components. The first additional component is fine gain transaction eficiency implied by reduced rent-seeking when non-tarifi‘ barriers are removed The secornd component is fine scale economy finat is made possible by fine increased trade. The inclusion of file transaction and scale emciency also explains why fine allocation effect is relatively large in fine model than would be suggested by an inspection based on finis simple example. W: In adjusting Production. welfare increases in both countries to a level of 20. Pollution, which is linked to fine output, rises to 80 or 120. This step shows fine structural or specialization effect of trade liberalization. W: Here it is assumed finat induced by fine trade, bofin countries adopt stricter regulations, lowering emissions by 25 percent and output by 10 percent The change in output’is introduced here for didactic purposes. Insofar as reduced emissions lead to lower extemalities, fine output level might even increase. 2.4.2. Decomposition with Constant Regulation Level From fine values in fine table, fine calculations for disaggregating fine pollution efl‘ect can be made. First, we ignore fine step of increased regulations. This yields fine summary Table 2.3: 77 Table 2.3: Pollution effect of trade liberalization with constant abatement Country A Colmtry B Pollution Efi‘ect +14.3°/o . +50.0°/o Scale effect +41.0°/o +41.0°/o Allocation efi'ect -6.4% -6.4% Composition efl‘ect -l4.3°/o +12.5% The values for fine constant abatement case result from fine following calculations: 1. Total pollution effect: A) +14.3%; B) + 50 %; Calculation: m_1= Aflqfiflfiq Emrssronso 70 80 2. Scale effect: +41%; Calculation: yi—l=£-l U0 14.1 3. Output effect: + 33.3 %; (This is an intermediate step for calculating allocation and composition effect). Calculation: M24424 0:4er 30 4. Allocation (barter) effect: 64%; Calculation: l--U—' =1-—1-5— U0 14.1 The relationship between fine finree effects is: 1 + Output eflect = (1+ Scale eflectXl-l-Allocarr'on efl'ecr). 5. Composition effect: A) -l4.3°/o; B) + 12.5 %; 78 Cal culation' 1+TotalPoIlutr’onEflect _1 ___ A)l' 143 ,8) 1.5 l + OutputEflect 1.33 1.33 The various effects (for country B) can also decomposed graphically (Figure 2-4). Figure 2-4. Environmental effect of trade liberalization: Decomposition into scale, allocation and composition effect fluvial-hale- Pelhfiea change of Clea-good 2.4.3. Decomposition with Endogenous regulation level When changing regulations are incorporated, fine calculations are slighfiy altered (Table 2.4). Table 2.4: Pollution effect of trade liberalization with endogenous abatement Country A Country B Pollution Effect -22.8% +1.25% Scale efi‘ect +27. 6% +27.6°/o Allocation efi’ect o6.4% -6.4°/o Composition efl‘ect -l4.3% +12.5°/o Mulation efi‘ect -25.0°/o 425.0% 79 The adjusted calculations are: 1. Total pollution effect: A) -22.8%; B) + 1.25 %; Calculation: EEO—"5.2. — 1 = .4151 - 1;B)§1 - 1 Emissrons, 7O 8O 2. Scale effect: + 27.6%; Calculation: 5 -1 = i -1 U, 14.1 3. Output effect". + 20 %; Calculation: m-l =E—l Output, 30 4. Allocation effect: -6.4%; remains constant. 5. Composition effect: A) ~14.3%; B) + 12.5 % remains constant. 1 + TotaIPoIIutionEflect 1 A‘ 0.772 '3‘ 1.0125 Calculati I — = , m (1 + OutpurEfleCIXI + RegulationEffect) ’ 1. 2 0.75 ’ 1.2 0.75 6. Regulation effect: -25%; by assumption Despite fine changing output levels, fine 10 efficiency effect as well as fine composition remain unchanged by fine inclusion of an income effect. However, finis would not hold, if sectors are hit asymmetrically by production losses. 2.5. Preliminary Conclusions The fineoretical considerations in finis Chapter showed finat fine overall efl‘ect of trade on fine environment depends on a number of mechanisms finat often work in opposite direction A 80 fnnll understanding requires a general equilibrium analysis. This is important irn particular for four lessens finat can be drawn from the discussion. First, fine political process of regulation setting is an important factor in the trade and environment complex. It can be shown in an analytical model finat fine income efl‘ect on regulatory stringency can fundamentally alter fine environmental outcome of trade liberalization. This leads to file formulation of fine institutional optimism hypofinesis. Clearly, an empirical test of fine hypofinesis requires an explicit modeling of fine political mecharnism. Second, bofin fine industrial flight and fine poverty attraction hypofinesis require a concentration on fine composition effect. An empirical analysis of finese hypofineses needs to be able to filter out finis efl‘ect from fine ofiner emission-relevant factors, such as scale and regulation efi‘ect. Third, fine previous section showed finat fine scale effect and fine output of fine ecornorrny are not identical. Therefore, a focus solely on fine scale effect overestimates fine pollution impact of pollution Instead, an input based indicator of pollution intensity is needed. In particular, in fine context of trade fine allocation efficiency effect finat determines fine difl‘erence between scale and output efl'ect can be substantial. Fourfin, interactions between increased requirements for abatement are complex. On fine one hand, higher production costs can reduce output, and might cause firms to relocate. On fine ofiner hand, fine reduced extemalities increase fine potential total output of an economy. They also might have a feedback on fine composition of fine economy. An explicit modeling of finese mechanisms is also desirable. 81 A full understanding of finese interactions requires a complex model. It will be shown in fine next Chapter finat a CGE model is best suited for finis purpose. The model developed irn fine next Chapter will address finese four important issues. 82 CHAPTER 3 MODELING TRADE AND ENVIRONMENT IN A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM FRAMEWORK 3.1. Empirical Modeling Approaches The previous clmpters have presented a considerable complexity concerning trade and environment irnteractiorns. The first part of finis chapter describes and evaluates difl‘erent mefinodological approaches finat are available for an empirical analysis of fine various trade and environment hypofineses. It will justify fine choice of a computable general equilibrium analysis for fine present study. The model itself is developed in fine second part of finis chapter. Ideally, an empirical analysis ought to integrate fine important feedback mechanisms to fine largest possible extent No empirical mefilod takes account of all such mechanisnns. However, a few approaches could provide fruitful insights in understanding and quantifying fine various relationships. One can organize finese approaches into finree major groups. A first way of exploring fine trade and environment relationship is fine case-study approach; file second approach is to econometrically estimate fine pertinent relationships; finirdly, one can apply econorrnic simulation models, especially computable general equilibrium (CGE) models. The distinction among finese finree approaches is in practice not quite as sharp as fine taxonomy might suggest. Simulation models, for instance, rely on econometric estimates or use estimates derived from case studies. Depending on fine case at hand, it is possible or even advisable to adopt hybrid approaches. Neverfineless, for a full appreciation of file choices irn empirical modeling it is useful to examine briefly fine finree basic approaches. 83 3.1.1. Econometric Approaches Some econometric studies of fine tradeenvironment relationship were discussed in previous chapters. They focus eifiner on trade flows or on foreign direct investment, and relate finem to indicators of environmental stringency. As discussed previously, despite some progress in understanding fine problems, finese studies fail to fnrrnly establish a conclusive link between environment and trade. Alfinough fine econometric approaches have a rigorous fineoretical fi'amework, fine available data are generally too weak to allow a conclusive estimation Statistical difiiculties appear at numerous levels. 1, 195m g Q; Hgfigher-Ohlin filegry The Heckscher-Ohlin fineory of comparative advantage, on which much of fine argument in file previous two chapters rests, is dificult to prove empirically, alfinough it remains fine nnost important fineoretical framework in international econonnics. Notably, it took several decades to solve file sorcalled Leontief paradox. In his senninal article, Leontief (1954) showed finat fine capital-redundant United States apparently exported labor-intensive goods. The article sparked an abundant literature that eifiner developed fineoretical modifications to fine simple Heckscher- Ohlin model (e.g., fine inclusion of product cycles) or pointed out biases in fine data construction (e. g., fine assumption finat imports use fine same production technology finat is used in fine U.S.). Also it is difficult to get pre- and post-trade prices. Naturally, an analysis of fine significance of fine environmental stringency in determining trade flows will be even more difficult filan fine analysis of labor and capital endowment Furthermore, a time series analysis of one country would need to include environmental policies in fine main trading partners. An increasing regulatory stringency of a country does not 84 imply a decreasing attractiveness for pollution-intensive industry, if environmental policies in ofiner countries evolve faster. We: For cross-country comparisons, no clearly identified yardstick for environmental stringency is available. The various possibilities for such an indicator include government oufiays on environmental policy; participation in international agreenents; abatement expenditure figures; or fine number and value of environmental taxes and levies. However, fine choice of one indicator over anofiler will skew the result, because preferences vary among countries for certain type of instruments (e.g., taxes or regulatiorns). Similarly, fine oficial regulatory fiamework may not be supported by actual enforcement, key industries may be exempted from regulation or taxation, or inefficiencies in fine environmental policies may make fine same pollution reduction much more costly in one country finan in anofine. Also at file firm or sector level, a numbe of potential indicators of regulatory costs exists, such as abatement expenditures, fine number ’of inspections, fine amount of environmental taxes paid, and fine number of regulations. These measurements, too, can only be a proxy of fine actual importance of environmental policy for a finn's operation First, finere maybealargegapbetweenfineletteroffinelawandwhatisactuallyenforced Secondfine cost-efi‘ectiveness of an environmental policy can vary substantially. In fine extreme case, fine actual cost of fine abatement itself could be nearly zero while fine administrative burden to prove finat fine abatement took place could be quite high. Also, if one country achieves fine abatement reduction via a regulation but another via an ecotara the regulated company is likely to have a competitive advantage over fine taxed one, which in addition to its abatement costs has to pay 85 taxes for fine non-abated emissions. The taxed enterprise would react nnore sensitively to environmental policy finan fine non-taxed one. LMmurirlalem On fine output side, finat is, concernirng fine pollution level itself, dimculties lie not only in measuring pollution levels but also in defining meaningful ways of aggregating a multitude of difl‘erent pollutants. Solutions to finese problems often need to be found on a case by case basis. For instance, various indicators of environmental stringency could be compared using sensitivity analysis. An alternative could consist in aggregate indicators based on ad hoc weighting mefinods, toxicity weights, hedonic values, or principal-component arnalysis. Unfortunately, often even fine basic elements of such an index construction are hard to come by, as data collections of environmental factors exist only fairly recenfiy. A full time-series analysis is finerefore often impossible. 5 ri ' ment A furfiner statistical difficulty lies in deriving an abatement function. General data problems are exacerbated by fine fact finat environmental regulations are rarely relaxed but only increase in stringency. Therefore, regulations follow a common trend wifin technological process. This common trend means it is often not clear whefine a change in fine emissions is due to increased environmental stringency or to nmobserved technological processes, because multicollirnearity is likely to plague fine analysis. 65'] . As was discussed in Chapter 2, environmental stringency cannot be taken as exogenously given. This relationship requires fine estimation of a system of simultaneous 86 equations to establish cause and efi’ect Pitfalls in establishing causality also exist in ofiner areas. For instance, one could falsely interpret low abatement expenditures (in dollar terms) as having lax environmental standards in country. In reality finey might be fine result of a very cost- efi‘ective environmental policy, or in fire extreme, fine result of a policy finat leads to an exodus of pollution-intensive industries. Similarly, fine opening of a country to trade might increase fine relative importance of difi'erences in environmental regulatiorns, but improve technology dissemination. If one adds to finese issues just discussed, problems of imperfecfiy operating rrnarkets, erogenous shocks, or rigid prices, it is clear first an econometric analysis of trade arnd environment relationships is dificult In practice, it is likely to remain limited to testing simple relationslnips, for instance, fine direction of trade and investment as a fnmction of an index of regulatory stringency. Many more complex interactions are beyond fine reach of ecornometric mefinods urntil fine data situation improves substantially. 3.1.2. Case Studies The division line between econometric approaches and case-study approaches is not sharp, because fine data of an econometric study also ultimately derived fiom individual cases. However, a change in focus warrants a distinction. Econometric analysis concentrates on fine formulation and testing of falsifiable hypofineses, and applies standard statistical criteria to do so. Evidenfiy, finis approach can also be followed wifinin a case study. However, for fine case- study approach, as it is understood here, it is possible to remain purely descriptive or operate wifin simple inspection of data For fire issue at hand, sectoral or historical conmtry studies could provide suggestive insights. 87 W The advantage of file sectoral case-study approach is finat it allows us to look intensively at fine obvious candidates where environmental factors might play a role (one could think here of chemicals, metal production, etc.) and which are of great concenn fiom a policy point of view. For finese, it would be necessary to identify fine various technological options arnd collect data on fineir respective cost structure and environmental impact One would finer need to detect to what extent regulations or ofiner factors detemnine fine sector’s size and techrnological development One could place fine study by Wheeler and Martin (1992) into finis category. The aufinors arnalyzed fine dissemination of pulp production technology as a flmction of a country’s openness to trade. They could show finat economies finat are more open generally have fine nnore advanced (and clean) technology. However, it is questionable whefiner fine experience in one sector is anecdotal or can be generalized, because there is a risk of a selection bias when choosing fine sector. Furfire drawbacks are fine potential need of considerable data, in particular at fine firm level, that might make many potentially interesting cases impossible to conduct in fine first place. In addition, fine approach risks leaving important factors out of fine analysis, due to fine partial nature of fine analysis (in particular, finose finat affect fine policy process). 3 l 2 2 II ri ! 1 Historical studies of whole countries are one way to avoid fine problem of having only a partial (and finerefore possibly biased) look at fine trade and environment problem. The result of fine historical changes finat occurred in finese countries is finen extrapolated arnd qualified to provide an estimate of fine expected impact of a similar change. Hufoauer and Schott (1992) 88 applied finis approach for fine case of NAFTA The aufinors assume an arnalogy of fine Norfin American case wifin 31 similar countries finat have liberalized economically in fine past They derived fiom finese data an approximation for file economic changes induced finrough fine trade liberalization of NAFTA. In fineory, it might be possible to collect fine corresponding information on environmental factors for at least some of fine cases. However, it has not been until fairly recent finat organizations, such as fine World Bank (especially since the World Development Report 1992), fine OECD (1995) and fine World Resources Institute (1986), have begun to compile international statistics of environmental indicators. In practice, fineefore, one would have to rely to a signifiCant extent on ex post construction of data sets, usirng external information on pollution intensities. Alternatively, one could choose a more descriptive approach based, for instance, on people’s perception of fine development. If fine difi'lculties in constructing useful environmental data sets can be overcome, fine historical approach could provide useful first-order approximations of fine expected impact of trade liberalization on growfin and environmental variables. However, problems renain For instance, fine case of NAFTA is fairly urnique, because it constitutes a free trade area between a higlnly industrialized and a fairly poor country. The case finat may come closest to fine NAFTA is finat of fine 1986 accession of Spain into fine European Community (now European Uniorn). rs Still, Spain's EC membership differs fiom Mexico's membership in NAFTA in at least four respects. First, NAFTA does not provide for fiscal support for its poorer member. Second, NAFTA does not allow free movement of labor. Third, fine income difi‘erences between fine 89 US 3.1 35%: U.S. arnd Mexico are a multiple of finat between fine European natiorns. Fourfin, fine European Commurnity has an active policy aimed at hannonizing environmental minimum standards wifinin fine Community. Arnofiner critical factor finat speaks against using fine historical approach to analyze fire question of NAFT A's environmental consequences is that it provides little guidance on a disaggregated level, since fine composition of any economy is unique. Therefore fine historical approaclncouldsuccessfullyattainonlyagoodestimateoffinescaleefl'ectbutnotfine composition effect of trade liberalization on pollution. 3.1.3. Simulation Approaches Simulation approaches are distinct from bofin econometric approaches arnd case studies irn that finey principally do not need original data Instead, filey rely on constructing ecornomic nnodels wifin parameter values first are derived from literature reviews of econometric studies, case studies, engineering data, or even educated guesses. Wifin filese data fine modeler can analyze fine impact of counterfactual policy scenarios. Simulation analyses have fire clear disadvantage firat finey are irnherenfiy incapable of hypofinesis testing according to scientific criteria Their reliance on secondary data means finat fine modeling assumptions already contain fine outcome of fine analysis. For instance, if a trade nnodel contains an equation finat specifies environment as an important production factor, a simulated regulatory change will automatically lead to a change in fine trade pattern The '5 The other countries, Greece and Portugal, finatjoined fine EU in fine Southern enlargenent (1981 and 1986) are qualitatively different. Both already had largely fies-market access, due to an association treaty and EFTA menbership, respectively (Shelbume 1993). 90 scientific argument about fire importance of regulation remains limited to a discussion, whefiler fine original assumption is plausible. The discussion is complicated by fine fact finat a correct specification of one policy aspect can be overwhelmed by an incorrect specification of anofine' essential relationship. This problem is fine reason for fine unease of many ecornonnists wifin economic simulation models. It is often not immediately clear, which particular equation specification is fine driving force of a simulation result Consequenfiy, simulation models often remain black boxes to fine reader, unless a significant amount of time is invested irn exploring fine modeling details. Unfortunately, finerefore, model validation finrough peer review is often While sufi‘ering from a severely limited model validation, simulation models are often fine only mefinod of deriving at least an approximate economic analysis. As discussed data problems are likely to be overwhelming for an econometric approach, if a minimum arnournt of complexity is required Simulation models allow a complex analysis while avoiding fine data problem by using best available estimates. The importance of individual parameters can be tested using sensitivity analysis. Three types of simulation approaches are available. These are macromodels, input-output analysis, and finally CGE modeling. Masmmadels Macroeconomic models are based on observed statistical correlation among aggregate variables in fine past They are applications of econometric models, and as such shares some of fineir problems for fine estimation fine economy-environment interaction Therefore, macroeconomic models of trade and environment relationships are forced eifine to make simplifications in fine modeling structure or to impose external parameters into fine model structure finat are not derived wifinin fine same framework as fine econometric estimates. 91 For instance, in fine context of analyzing NAFTA, Adams et al. (1992) and Clopper Almon/Inforum (1992) applied macronnodels wifin fairly detailed sectoral disaggregation However, finey do not provide any disaggregated information on fine factors of production. An extension of fine models to include environment as a production factor is finerefore not straightforward In addition, most environmental data do not exist in suficienfiy detailed time series, but are at best available as simple point estimates.“ While macro-models have been medsmcessfirflymmewmsmncesmesfimeemonficefimoffiadewhemmmflydng fine field of economy-environment interactions, its use is limited. - M l Envirornrnent can be integrated in a straightforward way by extending an input-output matrix On fine input side, fine environment appears as a source of extraction and provider of recreation for industry and final demand. On fine output side, fine environment receives discharges of residuals finat occur during fine production or consumption of a good Like all ofirer sectors of fine [-0 matrix, the environmental sector can be furfiner disaggregated, eg into air, land, and water. ‘7 The first generation of simulation studies are Leontief models finat used finis type of extended input-output matrix to analyze policy changes (e.g. Rhee and Mirarnowski 1984). mOnanaggregatelevelfincreexists,however,agoupofottenhighlysophisticatedKLEMnnodels named after the four included input factors capital (K), labor (L), energy (E) and materials (M). These studies analyzed the possibility of an economy to substitute away from energy dependency afierfineoilshocksinthe l970s.Thesemodels,however,areparfialatbest,andareof1imited valucinanalyzingfinenwmmulfifaceedproblencenplexthatweamdealmgwhh. 92 Victor (1972) provides a comprehensive model of finis type for fine whole economy. Most ofiner enpirical models such as Cumberland and Stram (1976) are restricted to an industry-by- irndustry format A survey is presented in Forsund (1985). The usefulness of traditional input-output modeling is, however, limited by fine assumption finat all coefficients are fixed This means finat I-O models are generally not useful tools when it is assumed finat an economy undergoes structural change, as is fine case for trade liberalization. To a lesse extent, file implicit assumption finat statistically established structural relationships will continue to hold in fine future, vexes also ofiner approaches such as macroeconomic and CGE modeling. However, macroeconomic models allow mitigating finis problem finrough fine inclusion of trend variables. By contrast, in input-output analysis fine level of pollution only changes through alterations in the composition and magnitude of cornsumptiorr, or some arbitrary change in fine pollution coeficients over time. Input-output analysis finerefore usually overestimates fine efl‘ects of policy measures, since it does not allow for substitutions finat may nnitigate fine impact of fine parameter changes. Input-output calculations finerefore could only serve as an upper bound of plausible values. Any conclusions resulting fiom an extrapolation of finese results would have to be qualified. m l r E uilibri M ls Computable general equilibrium (CGE) models are hybrids of macronnodels and input- output models, combining fine advantages of bofin. The CGE approach involves fine construction "’ Ahmad, E1 Serafy, and Lutz (1989) and Costanza (1991) contain papers on the issues involved in producing environmental accounts. 93 of a model finat explicifiy incorporates fineoretical assumptions about fire behavior of individual actors. Most offine assumptions used in standard models are fine usual and widely accepted staple of economic fireory. CGE models generally postulate finat firms maximize profits subject to cornstraints set by technology, prices, interest rates, and so forfin, and finat fine behavior of cornsumers is determined by utility maximization subject to price and income constraints. These basic assumptiorns are usually extended to serve fine intention of fine modeler. Modeling economy-environment interactions, for instance, requires some explicit assumptions about fine form in which finis interaction takes place. Many CGE models use statistical estinnates for fine flmdamental fineoretical parameters. The missing parameters are obtained finrougln calibration (cp. Shoven and Whalley 1992). This approach means filey are chosen in sucln a fashion finat fine model reproduces a historical data set, called a Social Accounting Matrix (SAM), constructed for fine purpose of fine model. Therefore, CGE models use bofin point arnd tinne- seies estimates to derive behavioral parameters. However, file difference between macronnodels should not be overestimated (cp. CBO 1992, p. 68). Econometric models can be regarded as analogous to a reduced form of fine more explicifiy modeled CGE models, alfinough some difi'erences remain. The flexibility finat CGE models provide in analyzing complicated economic interactions has led to fireir wide application in fine fields of trade and public finance wifil a special interest in fine distributional impact of macroeconomic policy (Robinson 1989; Shoven arnd Whalley 1992). Some CGE models analyze fine economic costs of environmental regulations at fine regional level, and at fine national and international level, mainly wifin a focus on fine economic efl‘ects of reducing C02 emissions. Hoeller, Dean, and Nicolaison (1990), arnd Nordhaus (1991) provide surveys of finis kind of modeling. Some more recent examples are given by 94 Hazilla and Kopp (1990), Jorgenson and Wilcoxen (1990), Bergman (1991), Boyd and Uri (1991), Conrad and Schroeder (1993), Ballard and Medema (1993), Nestor and Pasurka (1993), and Perroni and Wigle (1995), Beghin et al. (1995), Copeland and Taylor 1995; Smith and Espirnoza 1996), Dessus and Bussolo (1998). The advarntages of fine CGE approach made it also fine prime choice for modeling fine efi'ects of NAFTA (CBC 1992). At least two dozen CGE models deal wifin various aspects of trade liberalization on fine Mexican economy, none of which focuses on fine environment. Reviews are provided in Shiells and Francois (1994), Brown (1992), and CBC (1993). Table 3-1 summarizes fine pros and cons of fine finree main empirical approaches. The overwhelming arguments in favor of a CGE model are its manageable data requirements and its analytical flexibility. Table 3-1. Comparison of different empirical approaches to assess trade and environment interactions Econometric Studies Case Studies Simulation /CGE models Data 0 high, problems of 0 medium 0 low Requirements multicollinearity 0 selection problem 0 use of best 0 diflicultiesin o useofmicro-and econometricestimates constructing proper macro-data possible indices Complexity of 0 simple, partial I complete analysis 0 high analysis analysis possible 0 allows experimental - could include policy forms Hypothesis 0 yes 0 focus on obvious I not tnnly possible, testing 0 estimation of candidates results driven by confidence intervals 0 descriptive assumptions 0 low generalizability 0 can filter out key relationships 0 sensitivity analysis Required . o mainlydata o needsdetailedfir'm o high,ifmodelisbuilt work load of construction level or institutional fi'om scratch analysis knowledge Existence of o few, inconclusive 0 some 0 plenty concerning literature trade relationships and environmental relationships 95 3.2. Non-Technical Model Description For fine purpose at hand, fine arguments overwhelmingly favor fine employment of a CGE model for fine analysis. However, even after deciding to use a CGE approach, finere are an infinite number of variants possible. These concern especially fine representation of fine environmental component, fine details of fine tax system, fine labor market, fine government sector, fine level of sectoral disaggregatiorn, and fine supply of production factors. Ideally, one would want to have a model finat is as complete and accurate as possible. In practice, a cost- benefit calculus guides model construction. While fine skill of fine modeler, fine existence of ofiner models, and data availability influence finis calculus, it is primarily driven by fine analytical focus. In the case at hand, it is evidently important finat fine environmental aspects of fine model are included in a careful manner. Clearly, however, in some cases dificult choices have to be made. In fine case hand, geographical differentiation and fine aspect of income distribution (which is important for its influence on regulation setting) had to be omitted fiom fine analysis. The description of fine model utilized in finis paper is separated into a technical and a non- teclnrnical part, which principally can be read wifinout fine other. 3.2.1. Overview To assess fine environmental consequences of trade liberalization empirically, a purpose- built computable general Equilibrium model of fine Trade Environment Relationships in Norfin America (ETERNA) will be employed. The newly developed model is comparative-static; it models a single period ornly. The model distinguishes four regions, namely fine finree NAFTA conmtries, Mexico, fine United States and Canada, as well as fine Rest of fine World. Wifinin each 96 NAFI‘ A country, finere exist four agents: firms, consumers, importers, and fine government. Output is based on finree primary production factors: labor, capital and air pollution ETERNA has 26 production sectors, most of which trade products wifin ofiner regiorns ‘ (Table 3-2). All sectors share a common production structure finat is depicted in Figure 3-1. As usual in finis type of model, producers choose fine optimal combirnation of inputs to mirnimize production costs, given fine level of sectoral demand and relative after-tax prices. Production in some sectors shows econonnies of scale. However, ETERNA maintains fine assumption of mornopolistic competition. This assumption means finat all sectors earn zero profits. Technology is assumed to be such finat fine decision-making process can be separated into several stages. " First, demand for final and intermediate inputs is allocated between imported arnd domestic supply. This allocation is the so-called Armington assumption, which etplaim cross-hauling of identical goods (Armington 1969). Second, domestic production results fiorn a combination of value added and intermediate inputs. Third, value added is a composite of labor arnd production capital. Fourfin, value added is associated wifil fine use of an envirornmerntal sink Fifih, fine environmental sink is a function of abatement capital and environmental pollutiorn, which in fine model includes only air emissions. The demand for fine sectoral outputs has finree components: finey are used as intermediate inputs to production, they are exported, and they serve for fine final consumption of each country’s houselnolds, which are modeled as representative agents. Households act as utility maximizes finat choose fineir Optimal. consumption bundles. ETERNA does not distinguish, as 97 is ofien done, between consumption and production sectors. Rafiner, fine final consumption of fine produced good enters fine utility function directly. " All production steps are hornothetic with a constant elasticity of substitution, which implies separability among subsets of different input bundles. 98 Table 3-2. Definition of Production Sectors for North American Social Accounting Matrix Sector Description 1. Agriculture Agriculture; Livestock; Forestry; Fishing & Hunting 2. Mining Coal products; Metal ore mining; Other mirning; Quarrying; Ofiner metal ore nnining 3. Petroleum Petroleun extraction & natural gas; Petroleum prodnncts; Basic petrochemical 4. Food Processing 5. Beverages 6. Tobacco 7. Textiles 8. Wearing Apparel 9. Leather 10. Paper 11. Chemicals 12. Rubber 13. Non-Metallic Mineral Products 14. Iron arnd Steel 15. Non-Ferrous Metals 16. Wood & Metal Products 17. Non-Electrical Machinery 18. Electrical Machinery 19. Transport Equipment 20. Other Manufactures 21. Construction ' 22. Electricity 23. Commerce, Restaurants & Hotels 24. Transport & Communication 25. Financial & Insurance Services 26. Other Services Meat & dairy products; Processed fiuits & vegetables; Milling of wheat & their products; Milling of corn & their products; Processing of cofi‘ee; Sugar & products; Oils & fats; Food for animals; Ofiner processed food Alcoholic beverages; Beer, malt; Soft beverages & syrups Tobacco & products Soft fiber textiles; Hard fiber textiles; Other textiles Wearing apparel; Hosiery; Knitted wear Leather & products Pulp; Paper products; Printing & publishing Basic chenicals; Fertilizers; Synfinetic fibers; Drugs & nnedicine; Soaps & detergents; Other chenical industries Rubber products; Plastic products Glass products; Cenent; Ofiner non-metallic mineral products Steel mills Non-ferrous basic industries Manufactnnring wood; Other wood industries; Furniture; Metallic structures; Metal forging; Other metallic products Machinery & non-electrical equipment Electrical machinery; Electrical appliances; Electronic equipment; Other electrical products Motor vehicles; Motor parts; Missiles & tanks; Ofiner transportation equipment Other manufacturing industries Construction Electricity, gas & water Commerce (wholesale & retail trade); Restaurants & hotels; Transport; Communications Financial services; Dwellings, real estate Professional services; Educational services; Medical services; Recreational & cultural services; Other services 99 Figure 3-1. Structure of the production function in ETERNA Households Indirect Exports Consumption El. CONS [oi Total Goods Supply xi CBS (Armlngton) Domestic Production mam” XDi la Leontief Indirect Inputs IO- . I Laontlat Value Added ENVirgs‘Tental VA, 5. CBS Exponential funefion - Labor = . ProductnonCapltal . Abatement Capital Pollution L e, llutlon KPI (W39 [:0 ) KA' POLL. 100 Trade relationships are modeled such finat fine balance of payments of fine different regiorns does not change. Included here are also fine flows from cross-country capital ownership. Demand for exports to a NAFTA country results from an Armirngton-type demand structure. Exports to fine rest of fine world follow a constant demand elasticity function, while supply fiom fine rest of fine world is perfectly elastic. Trade flows are subject to import duties, which are collected by fine government, which recycles finem back to the economy in a lump- sum fashion Non-tarifi‘ barriers are a sigrnificant obstacle to flee trade, which results in rents for fine importers. However, it is assumed that finese rents do not produce any benefit to fine representative agent, and are finerefore counted as net welfare losses. 3.2.2 Economy-Environment Nexus in the Model The important feature of ETERNA is fine economy-environment nexus. Five difi‘erent relatiornships can be identified: 1. Calculation of emissions 2. Extemality in file production function 3. Extemality in fine utility furnction 4. Abatement cost fimction 5. Determination of abatement level These relationships are shown in Figure 3-2. The numbers in fine Figure correspond to each identified relationship. There exists no model filat incorporates all 5 aspects. The simplest arnalysis integrates only fine first relatiornship. This integration can be achieved by use of a standard CGE model of trade liberalization and inclusion of an environmental input-output table as a simple add-on This approach has been taken by Grossman and Krueger (1995) who use fine existing model by Brown, Deardorfi‘ and Stern (1992) and calculate fine envirorunental 101 consequences through imputation of U.S. pollution intensity data into fine volume of trade. Tlneir results suggest finat fine environmental consequences of NAFTA will be negligible. Figure 3-2. Economy and Environment Interaction in ETERNA Welfare Utility EW '\ Health Consumption Production A externnality / Production Regulation atnuns Vat Emission V calculation . Pollution < Regulatron Lee and Roland-Holst (1997) analyzed file economic relationship between Japan arnd Indonesia by irnputing U.S. pollution intensities into fineir mutual trade. Even under fine arguable assumption finat fine pollution intensity of a sector in Japan is not lower finarn finat irn Indonesia, fine aufinors find a considerable asymmetry in fine pollution content embodied in fine exports of fine two countries. Indonesia exports pollution-intensive goods arnd irrnports goocb first are relatively clean. A CGE analysis of fine trade relationslnip points to considerable scope for policy instruments to reach environmental improvement at low costs in terms of GDP. In 102 many respects fine econonnic relationship between fine U.S. and Mexico is similar to final between Japan and Indonesia. However, in fine North American case, it is not evident finat embodied pollution flows from fine poorer to fine richer country. Bommer and Schulze (1996) who used a similar approach too Lee and Roland-Holst for NAFTA show first irn this case fine U.S. is a net exporter of relatively pollution intensive goods and becomes nnore so due fine irntroduction of NAFTA. The add-on approach provides a straightforward way to orgarnize data for a historical ecornonnic situation However, for fine analysis ofa counterfactual situatiorn, fine approach is too parsimonious. Changes irn fine pollution level are calculated out of fine resulting change irn sectoral composition fiom a model that ofinerwise completely igrnores envirornmental interactions. This approach is a special case of fine more general nnodel finat includes envirornmental feedbacks on production. Several CGE models consider fine efi'ects of regulatiorns on production costs arnd fine consequent clnarnges in output and trade. Alfinougln hampered by sketchy data, finere exist some interesting approaches for single country models finat include representations of emissiorns abatement fimctions, for instance, Dessus and Bussolo (1998). A direct applicatiorn to Mexico can be fonrrnd irn Beghin et al. (1995). Most of these models are, however, of a partial equilibrium nature in finat finey mly considerfinepotentialcostsbutnotfinebenefitsofenvirenmentalresfiicfionsandstandardson finenaticnalproductThisconsiderationisbecausebenefitsandcostsofchengesinfinelevelof polluticnaredificulttoobtain.Perroni and Wigle (1995) useanadhocflmctionalformthat measures fine welfare increase from a reduced pollutiorn level. Their analysis relies on a separability of pollution damage and cornsumption in fine utility fimctiorn The welfare efl'ect finus 103 has no impact on fine behavior of fine model itself. This outcome means finat, efi‘ectively, fine modelisrmLandfinewelfareefi‘ectiscalculatedlater. Ballard and Medema (1993) integrate producer-producer and producer-consumer extemalities into a CGE model of fine United States. The aufinors incorporate material damage irnto fine analysis tlnrough variable input-output coeficients. This approacln allows fine researchers to approximate fine costs of damaged output due to changes in fine polluticrn level finrough increases in fine demand for intermediate inputs of that afi‘ected sector. In addition cornsumer welfare is affected finrough a parameter afi‘ecting fine healfin of fine population. Similar approaches are followed by Copeland and Taylor (1995) and, in a trade, context by Snnifin and Espinoza (1996) Pireddu (1996) developed a closed-economy model that includes fine first four important envirornment economy relationships. This approach allows him to test a variety of environmental tax options. His model so far is calibrated only to a primitive “toy” ecornomy. However, in principle, the model could serve as a shell finat could be calibrated to actual data. There are two attempts finat are in spirit close to fine modeling assumptions described furfiner below. Cole er a! (1997) add emissions figures to an existing model simulation A pseudo-regulation firnction is imposed on their trade model by imposing a U-shasped emision function on top of fine results. However, since fine environmental Kuznets curve is fine result of bofin structural and regulatory changes, finis mefinod inherently leads to a double counting of fine structural clnange. By contrast Strutt and Anderson (1998) add a unit ennissiorns curve finat is estimated from surveys While finis work provides good detailed technical information, fine projected techrnological progress is not linked to trade, and could finerefore be deenned autonomous. 104 ETERNA fills a gap in fine literature by incorporating all five identified economy- envirornment relationships: The environment is modeled as an input factor. Production finat uses finis factor results in pollution finat damages fine healfin of fine population The use of file environment finerefore afl’ects direcfiy fine supply of labor in fine nnodel. This efi‘ect leads to lower production as a result of pollution due to sick days, reduced physical healfil, etc. The snnpply of labor is finerefore modeled not only as function of the real wage rate but also of fine general level of pollution. The use of fine environmental input depends on two factors. First, it is a direct function of fine output in fine various sectors. If a polluting sector grows wifinout any change in fine composition of fine inputs, fine pollution output increases. (Because ETERNA allows for economies of scale, finis increase will not necessarily be in proportion.) The second factor that determines fine pollution output is fine pollution intensity of production first is allowed by fine government. The government regulates fine amount of pollution each sector is allowed to emit pe nrrnit of production. Efi‘ectively fine use of fine environmental output also fixes fine amount of abatement capital per unit of production. In a firrfiner important step, fine level of fine abatement expenditure has been made endogenous to fine model, namely as a firnction of fine real income of fine representative agent. The motivation behind finis follows fine argument outlined in previous chapters finat a wealfinier population calls for a stricter level of environmental regulation. Therefore, insofar as fine policy of a country increases fine material well-being of its population, finere exists a direct feed-back to fine stringency of its environmental regulation It is finerefore not a priori clear what direction environmental changes will have in fine difi‘erent 105 countries, because fine composition of fine economy changes at fine same time as fine efi'ective supply of fine environmental input. To irnpute fine efi'ect of pollution on well-being (which is not linearly related to increased material welfare), overall welfare finerefore takes account of bofin changes in fine material well- being and of healfin. For finis feedback mechanism macro-epidemiological data are enployed first show fine effects of pollutants on healfin, sick days, and hence labor supply. However, three ofiner aspects finat are not addressed should be mentioned here for completeness sake. First, fine mecharnisms of economy-environment interaction, such as teclnrnology adoptiorn and are intrinsically dynamic in nature. A comparative static fi'amework glosses over finis aspect. Second, a focus on fine income elasticity of regulation neglects fine demand side efi'ect and consumption production patterns of higher income. A high demand elasticity for clearn product would have an impact on a country’s econorrnic composition and reinforce fine courntry transformation. However, many higlnly income elastic products, such as cars, are also pollutiorn intensive. The analysis furfiner below will however be based on a unitary income elasticity. Third,eveniffineanalysis showsfinatcountrytransfonnationhypofinesis holdsinagroup of countries that liberalize their trade, it cannot be excluded finat pollution in finird courntries irncreases. As fine country wifin fine previously lax regulation level improves its enforcennent, fine vey polluting industry might simply move on to ofiner places to satisfy fine large overall denand Next, a nnore detailed techrnical descriptiorn of fine equatiorns will be given. 106 3.3. Model Equations: Technical Specification In finis sectiorn, a nnore detailed and complete description is given of fine structure of ETERNA The calibration process and fine data used for fine numerical specificatiorn of fine modelwillbedescribed furfinerinsection 3. The description of fine model equations observes fine following notational conventions. Ouantities are capitalized (e. g. H) for domestic production); prices are in lower case letters (e.g. pxd for fine price of domestic output); parameters are denoted inn Greek letters (e.g. afor an elasticity) or spelled out completely (e. g. scale for fine ecornomies of scale parameter). To avoid notational clutter, country indexes are generally omitted, except where finey are necessary to describe bilateral relationslnips. Irndices used in fine description are production sectors (subscript) countries (subscript) , foreign countries (subscript) world (subscript) net of taxes (superscript) gross of taxes (superscript). magma-w 3.3.1. Production A dificult problem for CGE models is to specify fine production function. Like nnost models, ETERNA assumes a functional forrn wifin convenient mafinematical properties, irn particular constant elasticities of substitution. As described in fine introductory secticrn, in each country, production technology in fine 26 sectors follows a nested structure. In all irndustries, a fixed-coeficient matrix (Leontief fnmction) is used in fine top nest for intermediate values and fine value-added composite. The relationship fixes fine relative proportions of fine irnputs. For total output, however, ETERNA allows for scale ecornonnies, as outlined in fine following equation: 107 “hi 3.1 m, =[min(2ionj,VA,)] I where XI); = domestic production of good i, ioij = intermediate input parameter of good Xj into production of good i, VA: = value added for production of good, and scale: = elasticity expressing econonnies of scale associated wifin sector i. In fine second nest, value added is produced in a constant-elasticity-of-substitution (CES) production function, using labor and a capital-environmental sink composite. 'l 3-2 VAt = CES(KSi nit): (pi[fltKIJi—'J";l +(1— fliyi'i—lljn-lv where KP: = production capital, Li = labor used in production sector i, 4); = scaling parameter, ,6: = share parameter, and or = elasticity of substitution between labor and capital-sink composite. The finird nest is defined as a fixed-coefficient relationship between fine use of direcfiy productive capital in fine sector and fine environmental sink fnmction. The rationale for finis fimction is finat every production process not only consumes material irnputs but also produces undesired byproducts finat need to be removed from fine production process by a sink. Technically, finis is a production output. Mafinematically, however, finis component to fine production function can be defined as an input. 3.3 S , = 5, VA, where 108 S5 = sink function, and 5': = proportionality parameter. The sink again is a combination of two factors. The sink furnction can be fulfilled eifiner by ernnitting fine by-products of fine production process direcfiy into fine environment, or by installing abatement equipment (e.g., scrubbers). The sink follows a constant elasticity ftmction: 3.4 S, = 21,164,; where A1 = emission of air pollutants 1011' = pollution abatement capital employed in sector i 4' = positive parameter between 0 and l. Abatement expenditure finerefore yields decreasing returrns to scale. An increase in abatement expenditures by 1 percent leads to a reduction in emissions by 4 percent The total capital employed in production can be defined as fine sum of its components, productive and abatement capital: 3.5 KT, =KA, +KP, The usual profit maximizing conditiorns apply. At each production level, finerefore, fine costs of fine inputs equal fine value of fine outputs, which translates into fine followirng two demarnd fnmctions for labor and capital: ‘r 3.6 L, = -1—[p[(L"l-6-?—':]H + (1 e my" VA, lot 109 'r I-" _ 1 flax H 3.7 KT, -;[(1- 4W] +(1- 5)] VA, In equilibriunn, profits will be zero. At file top nest of fine production furnctiorn, finerefore, 3.8 pxd,”)fl), = 2pr101. +wL, +r‘KI} 1' where = gross price for intermediate inputs (a composite of domestic productiorn and imports); = wage rate; and r3 = gross return on capital. P14” = net price of domestic production in sector i; mi w It slnouldbenotedherefinatfine production input ofemissionsdoesnotappearinfine equafiatbecauseitisafieegoodfinatcanbeusedbyfinefinnwifinoutcharge.Howeve,as will be explained later, fine use of the environmental resources is not unlimited For value added, analogously, fine formula can be derived: 3.9 pvafVA, = wL, +r‘KT, 3.3.2. Households Households are assumed to have homofinetic utility furnctions and are finerefore modeled as a single representative agent The consumer’s decision problem is simplified in filis model due to fine absence of intertenporal decisiorns. No saving takes place. All fine consumer’s irncome is spent. Total welfare results fiom two components, namely material well-being, arnd a parameter reflecting fine healfin of fine population. Neifiner leisure nor savirng enter fine consumer welfare directly, as is often assumed in CGE models. This simplification has some irrnplicatiorns 110 for fine factor supply, as will be elaborated below. The relationship assumed here between healfin and material welfare is of a simple multiplicative nature. 3.10 T OTU = MATU( BASEHEALTH HEALTH J“ where TOTU = total welfare of representative agent; MATU = well-being due to consumption and leisure; HEALTH = healfin of fine population due to fine quality of fine environment; BASEHEALTH = base healfin of fine population due to fine quality of fine environment; and Ir = valuation of healfin. This relationship means finat fine valuation of healfin increases wifin fine general welfare of fine population. The demand elasticity of healfin wifin respect to total welfare is one. In principle, fine fimctiornal form could be chosen such finat it contains a lnigher elasticity. The simple form has been chosen here for finree reasons. First, fine expected changes in total welfare are not enough to make a major difl'erence between a linear or non-linear fimctional form Secondly, and more important, healfin is a multifaceted concept, finat is represented here irn a simple linear relationship, namely, fine number of days an average citizen is not ill. At an aggregated level, fine data situation is not adequate to justify choosing a more complicated fnmctional form Thirdly, in ETERNA, healfin cannot be chosen direcfiy by fine agent. Tlnis restriction means finat total welfare is only a reporting variable, rafiner finan a decision variable. Therefore, even wifin a difl'erent functional fornn, fine equilibrium outcome of fine model would not change. The valuation parameter 1: allows a calibration of fine welfare function finat provides direcfiy fine monetary equivalent of any change in fine healfin of fine population. Henlfin is affected by fine total pollution output of fine country’s economy. 111 3.11 HEALIH=I—qZA, l where 17 = positive pMeter. In ofiner words, healfin decreases as pollution increases, and it does so in a linear fashion. ETERNA assumes finat finis relationship is not affected by sector specific increases in expenditures, irn particular in healfin care (which is not contained in fine model as a sector), finat might mitigate fine impact pollution has on healfin It is, however, possible to irnterpret Equation 3.10 to include implicitly fine welfare-decreasing aspect of increased healfin-care expenditures. Furfinermore, equation 3.11 implies finat finere are no cross-country pollution efl‘ects. All pollution is finerefore assumed to be local. Consumer behavior is defined as welfare maximization of U, which is defined as :1 :1. it 3.12 MATU = CES(CONSU, 112150125) = [pcomu . (1 - ¢)LEISURE . J where LEISURE = Leisure CONSU = utility derived fiom consumption w = share paranneter r = elasticity of substitution between leisure and consumption of goods. The welfare component due to pure consumption is defined as t-_I i 3.13 CONSU = CES(Z CONS, ) = [Z a,CONS, . J where 112 CONS: = consumption of good i, a: = share parameter, and p = elasticity of substitution between fine various consumption goods. Consumers behave as welfare maxinnizers. Consequently, fine demand for cornsumptiorn goodsis l 3.14 CONS, = “"INCOW ill-o) I p -. px.‘ Z a; pr. 1' where INCOME = national income. Incorntrasttomarnymodelsoffinissort,finereexistsnodistinctioninwe1fareterms between private consumption and government consumption. Bofin are assumed to contribute equally to fine welfare of fine representative agent. Consumption is bournd by a budgetary cornstraint. 3.15 2 px,‘ CONS, = INCOME Income of fine representative agent itself stems from factor income and public transfers. 3.16 INCOME = w"L +r"KH + 25%, + TRANSFERS, q where 101 = domestic capital owned by fine home country = capital owned by domestic agents in foreign countries TRANSFERS = government transfers. 113 The factor income is separated into wages as well as capital income. To incorporate information on cross-country capital ownership, an explicit distinction is nnade here between capital owned by a country, and capital employed in a country. 3.3.3. Regulation Setting and Supply of Productive and Abatement Capital The total supply of capital is assumed to be constant. As was touched upon briefly when discussing fine welfare fimction, saving is not part of fine utility function. Capital formation is finerefore not endogenous to ETERNA, but is assumed to be fixed Capital can be used eifiner direcfiy for production or can be used for abatement. It is assumed to be connpletely mobile between sectors. At least in fine base model, however, it is not mobile between conmtries. The pre-existing cross-country capital ownership patterns persist 3.17 Z(KA,+KP,)=K 1 where K=totalcapitalinfineeconomy. Total capital'is owned eifiner by domestic agents or foreigners: 3.18 2K1 +KH =K 4 where K.q = capital owned by foreigners in fine domestic country In principle, fine supply of pollution is unlimited, wifin no direct constraint applying to it However, two components limit its use. The first one was already elaborated upon in fine production fimction in equations 3.3 and 3.4. These two equatiorns oufiine finat fine total demand 114 for fine sink furnctiorn is related to fine capital intensity of production. Furfinermore, finere is a substitution relationship between pollution and fine amount of capital spent on abatement Without imposing any costs on fine environment or constraining its use ofinerwise, pollutiorn would be driven to infinity. Therefore, fine model needs a mechanism to limit its usage. In . practice, in most cases, environmental pollution is limited via regulation that prescribes the use of certain pollution abatement equipment. More rarely is its use limited via a price mechanism. Whichever of fine two mefinods is applied, in mafinematical terms fine result can be expressed irn terms of a tax equivalent finat leads to an identical allocation of abatement and productive capital. In parallel to fine discussions in earlier chapters, fine allowed pollution intensity is seen as a fnmctien of the material well-being of fine country. Therefore fine use of abatement capital is determined by fine following equation 3.19 KA‘ = KAO‘ MATU‘ KTi KTOi where K210, = abatement capital in base case, KTO, = total capital in base case, and s = positive number (income elasticity of regulatory stringency as a fnrrnction of per capital utility). This relationslnip could also be interpreted as an implicit tax on fine productive capital finat is used for fine abatement of fine environmental pollution. The institutional arrangement is sucln finat fine government does not attempt to equalize fine marginal abatement costs across sectors, but changes fine stringency of regulation across fine board. This unequal regulating of various sectors may be fine result of limited information on side of fine government or political pressure. 115 3.3.4. Labor Supply Labor input to fine individual sectors is limited by fine overall supply of labor in fine economy. in ZL=L i This equation means finat ETERNA employs fine full-employment assumption All unemployment in fine model is finerefore voluntary. The supply of labor is derived from utility maximization finat derives fine demand for leisure. If we take fine total endowment wifin time as: 3.21 7M=LABOR+LEISURE 3.22 LEISURE: '. (1—¢)n:MTU - w" (0—31))“ +pmatu’") where pmam = marginal utility of income F urfinerrnore, labor supply increases wifin fine real wage rate finat is reflected irn fine parenfinesis of fine equation pmatu denotes fine true cost of living index, and is defined as I 3.23 pmatu = (Z a,PX,"' J H LABOR is to be understood here as fine time spent working. Its productivity is assumed to be also a fnmction of fine healfin of fine population, according to fine following functiornal form: 3.24 L = LABOUR- HEALTH It is finerefore assumed finat fine healfin of fine population has an effect not ornly on fine well- being, but also direcfiy on fine productivity of its labor. 116 3.3.5. Trade Final consumptiorn, exports, and intermediate inputs are a composite of domestic arnd imported products. Mafinematically, finis fine composite good is be described as an Armington aggregation, which means finat a CBS function combirnes imports and domestic productiorn: J t.-. a: 7537 3.25 x,=CES(.m,,zM,,)= p,.rD,T+z,.,,M,,‘t] 9 9 where Xi = Armington composite of good i in country k, Miq = Imports of good i into country k from country q, A = shift parameter, pi = shares of domestic production, pig, = share of irnnports, and (5' = elasticity of substitution. An Armington flmction is chosen because, ofinerwise, fine model may provide fine unrealistic result ofa complete production concentration of a certain sector in just one courntry. The derivation of fine Armington aggregate can be treated completely analogous to fine CES production functions described above. Demand for domestic production arnd imports, respectively, can be derived as: ml 3.26 M, =—’- (I—p,, ””p ‘9 8 “1,, X, ’1! Pipxdr' +Znuttpmlk k ’1 [-6, 7:}: 3.27 XD,=—1-(1-p, Jpri; +p, X, 1'1 ztuigpmtq 117 Zero-profit conditions result similarly in fine following price definition: 3.28 pxinXi = ZPMiquiq + Mimi ’ q where px,” = net price of Armington composite, pmiqg = gross price of imports fiom comntry q, and pxdi = price of domestically produced goods. In fine field of trade, a set of identities needs to hold for fine bilateral relatiorslnips. Exports fiom country k to country q must equal imports of country q fi'om courntry k Therefore, 3.29 E,” = Mm, where E11“, 8 exports of good i fiom country k irnto country q; and Migk = imports of good i by courntry q from conmtry k. Equally, export prices of country k must equal net import prices of country q: 3.30 pew = ping, where peikq = price of exports of good i from country k into country q, and pm"iqk = net price of irnnports of good i by country q from country k The goods supply fiom fine rest of fine world is assumed to be perfecfiy elastic. Sirrnilarly, fine exchange rates of all countries are fixed in irntemational currency, leading to fine equation: 3.31 pm; = m 118 where m = exchange rate of domestic currency expressed in terms of intematiornal currency. On fine ofiner hand, demand of domestic products by fine rest of fine world follows a constant elasticity function finat is driven by fine real export price. 3.32 5,, = E0,,[-pi'—) Em where v = demand elasticity of fine rest of fine world. The balance of payments of each country is defined as: 3.33 BOP, = 2298.45.14 - PmLMm)+Z(’q"e "We: ). r q 9 where BOP]; = balance of payment of country k, and qu = capital in country q owned by country k. The first component lists fine real trade flows, while fine second component denotes fine capital balance between fine countries. In equilibrium, fine sum of fine external balances will be zero. 3.34 ZBOP, =0 k 3.3.6. Taxes and Government The government fulfills finree functions. It collects various taxes and duties, it purchases goods, and redistributes revenues in fine form of transfers to households. Taxes included in 119 ETERNA are value-added taxes, sales taxes, taxes on capital, and labor taxes, resulting in fine following four equations: 3.35 pm,‘ =pva,"(1+tva,) 3.36 px,‘ =px,"(1+tx,) 3.37 r‘ =r"(1+tk,) 3.38 w‘ =w"(1+tl,) Imports are subject to ad valorem tariffs, wifin tmiq denoting fine tarifi‘ on product type i from country q. Furfiner, non-tarifi‘ barriers are also taken into account. They are similarly expressed irn fineir ad valorem equivalents, as miq- Using finese values, fine prices paid by fine consume for imports are: 3.39 pm; = pm;(1+tm,q +171”) The practical difi‘erence between rm and tn is finat fine revenues generated by on are recycled back to fine economy as goverrnment consumption (benefiting also fine consume). By corntrast, In is modeled as complete welfare loss due to rent-seeking behavior, following Arnne Krueger’s argument (Krueger 1974). 3.40 MORT LOSS, = m,,M,, Government provides a public good according to fine forrnala: 8 s-r — 3.41 PUBGOOD + CES(Z GOVCONS,) = [Zw,GOVC0NS,T)H i n' where 120 PUBGOOD = public good, GOVCONS,‘ = government consumption of good i, an = share parameter, and t9. = elasticity of substitution between fine various government consumptiorn goods. The provision of fine public good is assumed to stay constant for all scenarios. 3.42 PUBGOOD = PUBGOOD Because of finis condition, fine supply of fine public good does not enter fine welfare furnctiorn of households. The tax revenues finat are not consumed to produce fine public good are recycled back into fine economy via transfers. TRANSFERS: ZZthM +Ztva,,VA +Zor,,X +rkK+tIL+BOP- PUBGOOD 3.43 where BOP = balance of payment in base year The government transfers include also fine balance of payments in fine base year, which is assumed to be unchanged. This assumption has implications for fine closure of fine nnodel. Cornsistent wifin fine assumption of no household saving, fine government deficits are netted out in fine rrnodel. 3.3.7. Closure A final set of equations is needed in order for Walras's Law to hold In ofine words, in equilibrium, fine system is not allowed to have any excess supplies. Therefore fine supply of fine Armington aggregate must equal its demand: 3.44 X, = 216,210), + CONS, + GOVCONS, + 2E" + MORT LOSS, r q 121 The supply can be used eifiner domestically (as final consumption and as intermediate irnput) or for export This flexibility implies finat fine system is balanced via trade, or, more precisely, wifin a fixed balance of payments via fine export prices. Since all supply and demand functions in fine model are homogenous of degree zero wifin respect to prices, only relative prices are important for fine determination of quarntities of goocb supplied and demanded All prices finerefore need to be deflated by a numéraire. In ETERNA, finis was chosen to be fine international price level of goods. 3.45 E20? = 1 This final equatiorn completes a full description of fine mafinematical relatiornships finat define fine model. However, fine behavior of fine model depends crucially on fine parameter values finat are used for fine numerical analysis. Chapter 4 will discuss fine data on whicln ETERNA was calibrated. 122 CHAPTER4 DATA DESCRIPTION AND MODEL CALIBRATION This chapter describes fine calibration of fine ETERNA model described in Chapter 3. A first part presents fine social accounting matrix employed. It also presents some stylized facts of fine NAFTA econorrnies. The data presented in finis part are of little originality and overlap significanfiy wifin finose used by Roland-Holst et al (1994).19 These data are suficient for constructing a standard CGE model. Since fine contribution of finis paper consists mainly irn adding an environmental modeling component, fine construction of fine environmental data needs to be described more extensively in a second part This part also serves to oufiine fine rationale for finose modeling choices finat are inherenfiy data driven. 4.1 Stylized facts of the North American Free Trade Area 4.1.1. Social Accounting Matrix As fine most important data source, ETERNA uses fine social accounting matrix (SAM) finat was compiled by Reinert, Roland-Holst and Shiells (1993). The SAM is a statistical compilation of fine flow of funds situation for fine filree NAFTA conmtries. Unless stated ofinerwise, fine discussion below refers to fine data in finis SAM, which reflects fine situatiorn irn ”Deviationsfi'omtheirapproachhavebeenchosenonly formodelingconvenicnce,anddonot represent a substantive criticism of fineir paper. However, they are responsible for sornne divergence in the sectoral composition of the modeling results reported in Chapter 5. 123 1988, which is fine base year for fine arnalysis. The year is chosen because it lies before fine implementation of CAFT A. Sincefinennodel followsfinecreedfinatfinebenchmarkdatareflectaneconomyin equilibrium, evey dollar of fine flows of fimds is interpreted as an eficiency nmit wifin a price of 1. This interpretatiorn is difi‘eent fiom observed physical urnits, but reflects various qualifies of fineinputs.Forinstance, iffine wagesinonesectororornecountryarehighefinarnirnanofiner,it is assumed finat finis difi‘erence represents lnighe productivity. Irnplicifiy finis means finat finere is a pefect substitution between 10 workers canning 1 dollar an hour and one worke earning 10 dollars. The SAM provides infornnation on fine money flows in fine base year for a numbe of variables, namely domestic production (m), consumption (CONS), input-output relationslnips (to), imports (M), exports (E), balance of payments (BOP), sectoral (KT) and total profits (K), cross-country capital ownership (KD and K9), wages (L), and transfes (TRANSFERS). Furfinermore, fine flmds received by fine govennrnernt can be used to derive efl’ective collection rates for tariffs (rm), sales tax (Ix), value-added tax (tva), and capital (tit) and labor taxatiorn (II). It should be emphasized here finat all tax rates in fine model are efi‘ective net rates. This definition mearns, on file one hand, finat taxes and subsidies to file same sector are netted out On fine ofiner hand, fine rates used here may deviate substantially fionn oficial rates, because fine government (for one reason or fine ofiner) does not collect fine amount of rrnoney finat would ' follow fiom simply multiplying oficial rates wifin fine quantities reported This adjustment is particularly important in fine case of tarifi‘s, where, due to exemptions, fine efi‘ective collection rates are often substantially below fine omcial tarifi‘ rates. 124 m 'v A A special problem for fine CGE model is finat fine SAM reports a loss for fine United States automotive sector in 1988. The standard mefinodology finat equalizes capital endowment wifin profits would produce fine meaningless result finat fine capital endowment in fine sector is negative. In its place, we have taken fine average profit rate in fine sector for fine next 5 years (1989-1993), which is 5.7 percent of turnover. This value for profitability has been multiplied by fine sectoral turnover. The difference is carried along in fine model in form of a constant W A sectoral disaggregation of fine government consumption (i.e., of finose government revenues finat are not used for transfers) is not available fiom fine SAM They had to be taken from anofiner source. The sectoral breakdown of government consumption shares is taken fiom Ballard et al.(1985) and applied fine 26 sectors of fine SAM. These values are listed in Table 4- 1. Since a similar sectoral breakdown was difficult to obtain for Mexico and Cenada, fine same government consumption shares were used for finese countries. 125 Table 4-1. Disaggregation of government consumption shares Sector Percent of Sector Pecent of ' Government Government Consumption Consumption Agriculture 0.36 Iron and Steel 0.01 Mining 0.10 Non-Ferrous Metals 0.01 Petroleum 3.63 Wood & Metals 0.64 Food Processing 1.26 Non-Electr. Machines 2.30 Beverages 0.25 Electrical Machines 6.33 Tobacco 0.14 Transport Equipment 13.45 Textiles 0.09 Ofiner Manufactures 2.42 Wearing Apparel 0.39 Construction 27.96 Leafine 0.08 Electricity 4.18 Paper 2.76 Commerce 3.04 Chenicals 2.10 Transport & Commurn. 4.89 Rubber 0.73 Finance & Insurance 1.97 Non-Metal Minerals 0.05 Ofiner Services 20.85 4.1.2. Asymmetric Structure of NAFTA The United States’ economy clearly dominates fine Norfin Americarn Free Trade Agreement. In 1988 fine U.S. economy had a GDP of 4504 bn U.S. dollar. Those of Canada and Mexico were 438 and 163 bn U.S. dollars, respectively. These figures mean finat fine GDP of fine USA makes up over 88 percent of fine total NAFTA econonnies, while finat of Canada is 8.6 percent. Mexico’s economy is only 3.2 percent of fine total NAFTA economy. The U.S. also dominates fine trade of fine area Between 50 and 60 percent of Canadian and Mexican exports and imports are directed at fine United States. By contrast, finese two conmtries combined absorb only 20 percent of fine U.S. trade. Table 4-2 shows finat trade between Mexico arnd Carnada is small. These figures even underestimate fine one-sidedness of fine trade depmdency, because barer 5 percent of fine U.S. production is exported This share is much higher for fine ofiner two countries, wifin 12 percent for Mexico, respectively 15 percent 126 for Canada Unsurprisingly, finerefore NAFTA will afi'ect fine USA less finarn fine ofine two countries in relative, finough not in absolute terms. Table 4-2: Trade in billion U.S. dollars (1988) Importers Exporters USA Mexico Canada World USA - 16.840 69.802 340.262 Mexico 19.730 - 1.078 15.053 Canada 79.172 0.397 - 49.359 World 434.741 14.668 54.350 - 4.1.3. Differences in Economic Development of NAFTA States W Mexico’s economic development lags substantially belnind that of the two northern members of NAFTA In fine base year 1988, Mexico’s pe capita income is a nnere $2,000, while finat of fine Canada and fine USA are 316,500 and $18,000, respectively. However, Mexico looks nnore prosperous, when GDP is calculated based on purchasing power parity. Summers and Heston (1991) list 1988 per capita GDP of $19,851 (USA), $17,681 (Canada), and $5,323 (Mexico). The income distribution is Mexico is more unequal finan in fine ofiner two courntries. The wealfiniest 10 % of fine population in Mexico control about 40 % of fine income, while fine equivalent figure for Canada and fine U.S. is 25%. The aspect of income inequality is certainly innportant in explaining fine political mecharnism of regulation setting. Howeve, influence of income inequality on fine simulation results cannot be arnalyzed wifin fine ETERNA nnodelirng tool, which employs fine assumption of a representative consumer. 127 Wit Naturally, fine difi'erent levels of development are also reflected irn fine ecornonnic structure of fine countries. Tables 3a-c break down fine finree Norfin American ecornorrnies into 26 SOCTOI'S.20 Compared to fine developed NAFTA countries, Mexico has a fairly high share of primary sectors. The combined share of agriculture, mining, and petroleum productiorn is nearly 18 percent of is output, while fineir values for fine USA and Canada are only 5, respectively 8 percent By contrast, fine norfinem countries have a more developed tertiary sector. Trarnsport, commece, financial, insurance, and ofiner services combine to about a finird of fine U.S. and Carnadian econonnies. Their importance for Mexico is less finan one fourfin These facs rouglnly match fine standard patterns observed in developed and developirng nations. However, fine interpretation of fine statistical information finerefore requires some caution First, every sector is an aggregation of firms of various sizes and trades. These are treated as homogeneous alfinough finey do not necessarily react fine same way to ecornonnic policies. Second, and more problematic may be fine application of fine same sectoral definitiorn across courntries wifin a difl‘erent state of development, such as Mexico on fine one hand, and Carnada arnd fine USA on fine ofiner. This definition will be discussed in more detail for fine calculatiorn of errnissions factors in Secfion 4.2. The greate dependence on expors of Canada and Mexico finan for fine U.S. was already mentioned Sectoral figures for fine U.S. export shares never exceed 20 percent while in the 128 ofine two countries, up to 70 percent of a sector can go to foreign markes, mainly fine USA One can distinguish to some extent fine influence of natural endowmens-on fine natiornal ecornomy and consequently fineir exports. For instance, sparsely populated Canada is rrnore intensive finan fine USA in fine production of primary goods. More extreme is fine situation in Mexico. Petroleum constitutes over 40 percent of Mexico’s expors. This trade gives finis sector a level in importance finat is well in excess of what is share in total GDP would suggest The dependency on a single product group is anofiner characteristic finat Mexico has irn common wifin many developing countries. However, even before fine implementation of fine NAFTA treaty, Mexico was moving to a nnore diversified export base. In particular, fine large export and irrnport figures for transport equipment arnd machinery hint at fine great importance of fine maqur’ladora industry. Maquiladoras are export-processing zones located along fine Mexican side of fine US-Mexican border. In finese zones, companies enjoy exemptions fiom duties on impors innto Mexico when finey re-export fine producs back to fine United States (Hufoauer and Schott 1992). However, fine relative importance of fine special zones is likely to decrease, because fine NAFTA treaty reduces tariffs for all of Mexico. 3° Government services are not listed separately, but are integrated into fine sectors. 129 Table 4-3a: Key sectoral data for the United States Sector Produc- Value Denand Exports Imports Export Import tion (%) Added (%) (%) (%) share (%) share (%) (%) Agriculture 2.4 2.0 2.2 5.1 1.4 10.6 4.2 Mining 0.3 0.4 0.3 1.2 0.4 19.6 10.2 Petroleum 2.4 1.8 2.8 2.5 8.0 5.2 18.3 Food Processing 3.5 1.6 3.4 3.0 2.3 4.2 4.2 Beverages 0.6 0.2 0.6 0.1 0.7 1.1 7.2 Tobacco 0.4 0.3 0.4 0.7 0.1 9.0 2.4 Textiles 1.0 0.7 1.0 0.8 1.3 3.9 7.6 Wearing Apparel 0.7 0.4 1.0 0.3 5.0 1.9 30.9 Leather 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.1 2.1 6.8 58.6 Paper 2.5 1.8 2.5 2.8 2.5 5.7 6.4 Chenicals 2.4 1.5 2.2 7.7 3.4 16.2 10.0 Rubber 1.5 1.0 1.4 4.4 2.3 15.0 10.7 Non-Metal Minerals 0.8 0.7 0.8 0.6 1.3 3.7 10.1 Iron and Steel 0.9 0.4 0.9 3.2 2.5 18.5 18.5 Non-Ferrous Metals 0.8 0.4 0.9 0.6 1.8 3.8 12.8 Wood & Metals 3.2 2.5 3.2 3.4 4.3 5.4 8.4 Non-Electr. Machines 1.9 1.3 1.9 6.3 6.0 16.8 19.9 Electrical Machines 3.4 2.7 3.8 10.3 15.0 15.0 24.8 Transport Equiprrnent 3.7 2.4 4.0 16.1 17.2 21.6 27.5 Ofiner Manufactures 1.1 0.9 1.3 2.3 6.2. 10.7 29.1 Construction 7.0 5.1 6.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Electricity 3.3 3.5 3.8 0.1 8.5 0.2 14.0 Commerce 11.7 12.7 11.0 10.0 0.0 4.3 0.0 Transport & Cornmun. 4.8 5.9 4.8 5.9 5.1 6.1 6.8 Finance & Insurance 14.3 16.3 14.0 5.8 2.1 2.0 1.0 Ofine Services 25.3 33.5 24.7 6.4 0.4 1.3 0.1 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 5.0 6.3 130 Table 4-3b: Key Sectoral Data for Mexico Sectors Produc- Value Denand Exports Imports Export Import tion (%) Added (%) (%) (%) share (%) share (%) (%) Agiculture 7.9 7.9 8.5 3.7 8.4 5.8 11.5 Mining 1.4 1.6 1.1 3.1 1.5 29.1 14.8 Petroleum 8.3 3.4 3.4 41.5 2.5 63.2 8.8 Food Processing 8.8 5.6 9.1 3.1 5.7 4.4 7.3 We 1.6 1.0 1.6 0.9 0.5 7.3 3.3 Tobacco 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.0 4.8 0.1 Textiles 1.5 1.2 1.5 0.9 1.5 7.9 11.2 Wearing Apparel 1.3 0.8 1.2 1.6 1.2 15.7 11.3 Leather 0.8 0.7 0.8 0.7 0.7 10.0 9.4 Paper 1.8 1.6 2.1 1.4 4.3 9.9 23.9 Chenicals 3.6 2.4 4.0 4.9 9.1 17.6 26.3 Rubber 1.0 0.8 1.3 1.3 4.2 16.2 36.5 Non-Metal Minerals 1.6 1.9 1.6 0.3 0.7 2.7 5.4 Iron and Steel 1.4 1.1 2.2 1.3 8.0 11.6 42.4 Non-Ferrous Metals 0.8 0.7 0.7 2.2 1.7 36.5 29.2 Wood & Metals 2.5 1.3 2.5 3.7 4.6 19.3 21.0 Non-Electra Machirnes 0.9 1.0 2.6 2.9 17.7 39.5 78.2 Electrical Machines 1.8 1.4 1.4 10.1 7.9 71.5 64.2 Transport Equipment 3.3 2.6 3.6 12.9 16.9 50.2 54.7 Other Manufactures 0.9 0.6 0.8 3.3 3.0 47.6 42.7 Construction 6.7 3.9 6.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Electricity 1.2 1.4 1.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Commerce 17.4 26.6 17.6 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Transp. &Connmun. 6.1 7.7 6.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Finance & Insurance 5.8 7.8 5.9 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Ofiner Services 11.6 15.1 11.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 12.7 11.6 131 Table 4-3c: Key Sectoral Data for the Canada Sector Produc- Value Denand Exports Imports Export tion (%) Added (%) - (%) (%) share (%) share (%) (%) Agriculture 3.6 3.4 3.1 5.0 1.4 20.8 7.1 Mining 1.5 2.7 1.5 2.5 2.6 25.7 26.2 Petroleum 3.3 2.0 2.7 7.0 3.1 31.6 16.8 Food Processing 4.1 2.4 4.1 2.3 2.8 8.6 10.2 Beverages 0.7 0.6 0.7 0.4 0.6 8.8 12.7 Tobacco 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.0 4.3 1.6 Textiles 0.7 0.6 0.9 0.7 2.1 16.2 36.2 Wearing Apparel 0.8 0.7 1.1 0.4 2.0 6.7 27.8 Leather 0.2 0.1 0.3 0.1 1.0 12.8 53.4 Paper 4.1 3.8 2.7 11.7 2.4 42.6 13.3 Chennieals 1.9 1.9 2.6 0.7 4.9 5.2 28.3 Rubber 0.8 0.8 0.9 1.3 2.0 22.6 31.1 Non-Metal Minerals 0.8 0.8 0.9 0.9 1.2 15.8 21.5 Iron and Steel 1.2 1.0 1.3 1.5 1.7 18.6 20.0 Non-Ferrous Metals 1.0 1.0 0.9 2.8 1.8 40.4 30.8 Wood & Metals 3.9 3.4 3.5 7.5 4.5 28.3 19.3 Non-Electr. Machines 1.8 1.0 2.7 5.8 12.0 49.4 66.9 Electrical Machirnes 2.0 1.7 2.5 4.1 7.9 31.1 46.8 Transport Equipment 6.7 3.1 5.9 30.3 24.9 67.8 63.4 Other Manufactures 1.0 0.7 1.3 2.2 4.6 34.2 52.0 Construction 10.5 8.6 10.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Electricity 2.2 3.6 2.1 0.5 0.1 3.7 0.6 Cornrrnerce 12.8 17.9 12.5 3.2 0.9 3.7 1.0 Transp. & Cornmun. 7.6 8.0 7.1 5.6 2.2 10.9 4.6 Finance & Insurance 8.4 10.2 9.1 0.8 5.4 1.5 9.0 Other Services 18.2 19.8 19.0 2.7 7.8 2.2 6.1 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 15.0 15.0 132 I l . . Table 4-4 shows fine capital to labor ratios of fine various sectors. The values are calculated fiorn fine factor rewards, where capital is defined as fine sum of profis arnd irnterest payments, and labor denotes fine gross wage bill. It is remarkable finat fine ratio of capital to labor irnpus in fine economy is five times higher for Mexico finan for fine USA and Canada (first finree columns of fine Table 4-4). This value appears to be in stark contrast to fine common peception of Mexico as being labor-abundant and fine USA and Canada as being capital abundant However, fine capital-labor ratios reflect degrees of eficiency in fine two econonnies. The capital-labor ratio in fine U.S. is lower finan finat of Mexico because American wages are higlner finarn Mexicarn wages reflecting higher U.S. labor productivity. Considering finis aspect of labor eficiency, fine United States and Canada end up being actually more labor-abundant finan Mexico, alfinough one unit of production requires a larger number of hours worked in Mexico finarn irn fine ofine two countries. Barring large differences in fine elasticity of substitution between labor and capital, one would expect finat across countries fine capital-labor ratios of fine individual sectors would vary nnore or less in parallel. To analyze finis aspect, fine last finree columns of file table present fine ratios of fine first finree columns nonnalized by dividing finem by fine average capital-labor ratio. Clearly, fine difi’erence between Mexico and fine ofiner two states is decreased. Even so, fine U.S. and Canada remain more similar in file relative labor-capital abundance of fineir input structure finan Mexico wifin eifiner of fine two. A part of fine variation in fine labor-capital intensities is likely to be a statistical artifact. Among countries finee are difi'erences in fine composition of production wifinin fine irndividual sectors is likely to vary systematically among courntries. Furfinermore, fine statistical defirnitiorn 133 of fine sectors nnight be artificially influenced by fine industrial organizafion of a sector. If a company out-sources part of is activities, finey will be registered as production of fine sector in which fine supplier is categorized. Anofiner explanation lies in actual teclnrnological difi‘erences. These will be more prevalent between Mexico and fine ofiner two countries finan between Canada and fine US. Furfinennore, fine interpretation of Mexico as labor-scarce is a simplification Mexico is probably scarce in skilled workers, while finere is no lack of unskilled labor. The productivity of unskilled labor is, however, highly dependent on fine existence of a trained middle marnagement to put finem to fineir best use. The degree to which fine lack of highly skilled labor afi‘ecs productivity will be difi‘erent across sectors. For irnstance, fine production of electricity is likely to have little use of unskilled workers, which would explain finat fineir production structure is nearly fine same everywhere. By contrast, in fine sectors whee one would most likely suspect sweashop conditions, fine diffeences in labor intensity are fine higlnest, e.g. for textiles, apparel and leafiner, arnd also in food processirng and certain rrnanufacturing sectors. It is finese sectoral differences in input intensities across courntries finat are important in explaining why sectors react difi‘erently to changes in fine trade regime. 134 Table 4-4 Table 44. Sectoral capital-labor ratios Sector Ratio of Capital to Labor shares Ratio of Capital to Labor shares (absolute values) (Country averages = 1) USA Mexico Canada USA Mexico Canada Agriculture 1.4 4.1 1.5 2.3 1.3 2.4 Mirnirng 0.4 2.1 0.9 0.7 0.7 1.4 Petroleum 2.8 7.6 1.3 4.6 2.5 2.1 Food Processirng 0.6 5.0 0.5 1.0 1.6 0.7 Beverages 0.5 3.1 0.7 0.9 1.0 1.1 Tobacco 1.9 3.0 1.2 3.1 1.0 1.9 Textiles 0.3 2.2 0.3 0.4 0.7 0.5 Wearing Apparel 0.2 2.7 0.2 0.4 0.9 0.3 Leafiner 0.6 1.8 0.1 0.9 0.6 0.2 Paper 0.4 3.4 0.5 0.6 1.1 0.7 Chenicals 0.7 3.3 0.8 1.2 1.0 1.3 Rubber 0.3 2.5 0.2 0.5 0.8 0.3 Non-Metal Minerals 0.3 3.7 0.5 0.4 1.2 0.8 Iron and Steel 0.1 2.5 0.3 0.1 0.8 0.4 Non-Ferrous Metals 0.2 3.4 0.7 0.3 1.1 1.0 Wood & Metals 0.2 2.8 0.2 0.3 0.9 0.3 Non-Elect. Machines 0.2 2.3 0.3 0.4 0.7 0.5 Electrical Machines 0.2 1.9 0.3 0.4 0.6 0.5 Transport Equipment 0.1 2.3 0.3 0.2 0.7 0.4 Other Manufactures 0.5 4.1 0.2 0.8 1.3 0.4 Construction 0.1 0.5 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.4 Electricity 1.8 1.9 2.0 3.1 0.6 3.1 Commerce 0.3 4.0 0.2 0.5 1.3 0.4 Transp. & Commun 0.4 2.4 0.4 0.7 0.8 0.7 Finance & Insurance 1.8 3.3 0.5 3.0 1.0 0.8 Ofiner Services 0.2 0.8 1.1 0.4 0.3 1.8 AVERAGE 0.6 3.1 0.6 1.0 1.0 1.0 135 .4 £32 (I) \ _ the taxes in instance, gr businesses and capital indirect tax Fir United St: govcmma i“Stance t °V€fWhelr Schott 19. 13.5mm Mexico is also set apart by fine structure of its taxes. Table 4-5 lists fine composition of fine taxes in a simplified structure that is also adopted in fine general equilibrium model. For irnstarnce, government subsidies to enterprises are netted out; property taxes and taxes on businesses are treated as taxes on capital; taxes on households are allocated to taxes on labor and capital; government transfers reduce fine labor taxes; sales and “sin” taxes are listed as irndirect taxes. Neverfineless, fine stylized structure of fine tax is in some aspects quite revealing. First, fine effective tax collection of Mexico is only half of finat of Canada and the United States. However, finis tax collection rate does not necessarily mean finat fine Mexican government has a comparatively lesser influence on its economy than fine other countries. For, imtance fine government still controls PEMEX, fine petrol monopoly, which has such an overwhelming importance on Mexico’s exports and, hence, fine overall economy (Hufoauer and Schott 1992 ). However, finis control does not show in fine tax statistics. Second, while fine most important taxes are labor-related for fine United States arnd Canada, finis share is rafiner small for Mexico. Instead, fine country relies primarily on indirect taxation and value added taxation. It is likely finat finese shares are simply fine result of greater ease in collecting finenn, rafiner finan a strategic choice on part of fine Mexican government. 136 Table 4-5. Taxes Capital in: Indirect ta Value add Duties Effective t: collection Note: Figt taxes, etc. 4.1.4. Tra Table 4-5. Structure of tax collection in the NAFTA countries USA Mexico Canada Taxes bn S % of taxes bn S % of taxes bn S % of taxes Labor tax 800 51.2 5 19.0 64 41.8 Capital tax 369 23.6 7 25.1 35 23.3 Indirect tax 376 24.1 9 31.9 49 32.2 Value added tax 0 0.0 6 21.3 0 0.0 Duties 16 1.1 1 2.9 4 2.4 Efiective tax 1562 34.7% 28 17.2% 153 34.8% collectiorn of GDP of GDP of GDP Note: Figures are net of subsidies and consolidated, e. g., excises are integrated irnto indirect taxes, etc. 4.1.4. Trade Protection before NAFTA Mate: The efi‘ect of fine trade liberalization implied by NAFTA depends crucially on fine pre- existing trade barrier. Table 4-6 lists fine tariff levels (variable In: of fine model) of fine finree NAFTA members applied in 1988. The numbers in the table do not report omcial tarifl‘ rates but effective collection tarifl‘ rates. Mafinematically finis is fine value of customs revenues divided by fine value of imports. There are some marked difi‘erences among fine sectors. Tariff collection rates are high for textile and apparel imports in Canada and fine US, but for other sectors no simple system emerges finat explains fine various levels of tarifi' collection. Overall, fine efi'ective tarifi‘ collection in all finree countries is surprisingly low, being on average between 1 and 5 percent among fine finree NAFTA partners. Reasons are, first, finat large arnournts of imports finat are not covered by tariffs, for instance fine maqur’ladora industry. Second, fine collection rates are likely to under-report fine actual protection finese tarifl‘s exert: fine average rate is not identical wifin fine marginal tarifi‘ rate. In fine extreme case, a tarifi‘ may be so high that it is prohibitive for any trade. This extreme would result in an efi‘ective tarifl‘ collection of zero, which might give fine false impressiOn finat finere is no trade barrier at all. 137 Table 4— Rol barriers, Paperwor] (Table 4-7 smom ta and the Con "Mel, the Value Offine 1055 Table 4-6: Etfective Tariff Collection of North America (in percent of import value) USA Mexico Canada ROW Can- Mexico ROW USA Can- ROW USA Mexico ada ada Agriculture 1 2 6 0 l 0 l l 2 Mining 0 O l 0 2 0 0 0 0 Petroleum 1 0 0 l 4 0 0 0 0 Food Processing 4 2 6 l 3 2 4 4 5 Beveages 3 3 2 0 0 0 35 35 35 Tobacco 10 17 8 0 0 0 8 8 0 Textiles 10 6 7 3 2 0 12 12 12 Wearing Apparel 19 9 l6 5 2 O 18 18 20 Leather 9 22 5 0 l 0 l3 l3 0 Paper 1 0 2 2 2 3 4 4 0 Chenicals 5 l7 2 2 3 0 5 5 8 Rubber 6 10 4 4 l 0 7 7 0 Non-Metal Mineals 6 l 0 4 8 0 5 5 8 Iron and Steel 4 3 3 l 4 0 4 4 5 Non-Ferrous Metals l l 0 2 4 O 2 2 0 Wood & Metals 4 l 2 4 3 0 6 6 6 Non-Elect. Mach 3 l l 5 3 5 2 2 2 Electrical Machines 3 2 3 7 l 5 4 4 4 Transport Equip. 3 O 2 l 2 1 7 0 7 Othe' Manufactures 4 l 3 2 10 0 4 4 5 All 5 l 3 3 2 2 7 3 5 1 i - El . Roland-Holst et al. (1994) provide important supplementary information on non-tarifi' barriers, such as quotas, voluntary export restraints, rules of origirn, and burdensome paperwork This effective trade protection is trarnslated into an ad valorem tariff equivalent (Table 4-7). The aufinors calculated fine figures from a composite of three sources: fine observed sectoral tarifi' collection rates in fine SAM; independent sectoral estimates by ofiner researchers; and fine combined UNCTAD-GATT database of four-digit SlTC trade control measures. In fine model, non-tarifi‘ barriers (tn), are calculated simply as fine difi‘erences between fine tariffs and fine value of fine table. A multiplication of fine figures wifin actual imports allows fine calculatiorn of fine loss finrough rent seeking (MORTLOSS). 138 particu hadfine lowest complen apparel. where it Non-tarifi‘ barriers in Norfin America were quite substantial in 1988. They were particularly high against Canadian exports. Bofin Mexico and fine United States tend to be more protectionist against Canada finan against fine rest of fine world or each ofiner. The United States had fine highest average import barriers against its neighbors, and Canada maintained fine lowest Mexico and fine USA were highly protectionist in primary exports.21 Mexico and Canada focus nnost of fineir protection on agricultural imports. There is also a certain complementarity at work. Where barriers are high in fine two norfinem countries (e. g., textiles, apparel, and leafiner), finey are low in Mexico. Conversely, Mexico applies high trade barriers, where it is not competitive (e.g., paper). Here fine ofiner two countries apply low protection rates. 2“Ihereare,lnoweveranumberofzerost‘orMexicanbarrier'sagainstCanada.However,thismay beeithcrastatisticalartifacteithcrbecauselowtradevolumesfinatdonotallowforbctter estimates,orthattheMexicangovemmentdidnotneedtobofinertoimpedethealreadysmalltrade flowsbetweenthetwocountnies. 139 Table 4—7 Table 4-7: Ad valorem estimates for North American import protection (tariff and non-tariff barriers in percent of pre-tariff import value) USA Mexico Canada ROW Can. Mex. ROW USA Can. ROW USA Mexo Agriculture 24 14 42 84 84 100 81 83 99 Mining 4 6 37 O 2 0 1 O 0 Petroleum 92 65 98 86 89 0 25 48 7 Food Processing 27 23 22 95 101 82 58 58 78 Beverages 97 97 92 100 100 0 35 35 35 Tobacco 21 81 23 100 100 0 8 8 0 Textiles 51 6 85 3 2 0 85 79 103 Wearing Apparel 19 9 l6 5 2 0 18 18 20 leather 9 22 5 2 3 0 105 103 39 Paper 1 o 2 64 66 87 s 4 0 Chemicals 7 18 9 9 7 9 l4 l2 8 Rubber 1 1 17 5 4 1 0 9 9 0 Non-Metal Mineral 9 1 57 7 1 1 O 19 14 l 1 Iron and Steel 83 48 75 47 43 0 86 74 95 Non-Ferrous Metal 2 l 0 2 4 0 2 2 0 Wood & Metals 13 5 10 4 3 O 16 14 9 Non-Electr. Machin l 1 2 1 7 4 5 3 2 2 Electrical Machines 13 7 3 13 8 l 5 5 6 4 Transport Equipme 71 65 6 13 19 1 68 57 83 Ofiner Manufactures 28 3 24 3 11 O 30 17 17 Economy-wide 28 38 10 25 15 26 36 31 32 Source: Roland-Holst, Reine" and Shiells 1994 140 4.1.5. £1 Tl elasticitil al (1994 demand The figu output b: In value of The leisn of the ut SubStitutj demand I 1.4 and] 4.1.5. Elasticities The responsiveness of an economy to policy changes depends on various economic elasticities. Table 4-8 lists fine most important elasticities. They are taken from Roland-Holst et al. (1994). The labor-capital elasticity of substitution (0), fine Amnington elasticities (6), and fine demand elasticity of fine rest of fine world (v) are defined according to standard conventions. The figures for elasticity of scale (scale) imply finat an increase in irnputs by X % increases outputby(1+X%)l+'"'°-l. In addition, fine uncompensated wage elasticity of labor supply is assumed to lie at a value of 0.10, fine compensated value is at 0.15. This is fine value derived by Burfiess (1987). The leisure endowment and fine leisure-consumption elasticity of substitution (1’) in fine top nest of fine utility function are calibrated to reproduce finese values. Furfinermore, fine elasticity of substitution for private demand (p) is set to a value 1.5. The equivalent value for government demand (.9) is set to be equal to one. This value translates irnto own price elasticities between 1.4 and 1.5.22 2“InaCES function,uncompensatedpriccelasticityequals -a'- (1-0) a, whereoistbe substitutionelasticity,andaisfineconsumptionshareofasector.Sincevaluesforaarelowdueto high disaggregation, theprice elasticities renain closeto a, whichis setat 1.5. 141 Table 4-8 Food Prom Table 4-8: Various elasticities by sector for all regions Elasticity of Scale Labor-Capital Elasticity of Armington Elasticities Dem- (in %) Substitution and - Enact Sector USA Mex Can USA Mexico Canada USA Mexico Canada ROW Agriculture 0 0 0 0.680 0.768 0.680 1.500 1.500 2.250 4 Mining 5 5 5 0.900 0.950 0.900 1.062 1.062 0.781 5 Petrolelm 10 10 8 0.861 0.861 0.861 0.660 0.660 0.580 20 FoodProsessing 18 18 12 0.710 1.100 0.710 0.889 0.889 1.007 4 Beverages 13 13 18 0.710 1.100 0.710 0.326 0.326 0.726 3 Tobacco 7 7 24 0.708 1.100 0.708 1.008 1.008 1.008 3 Textiles 9 9 14 0.900 1.100 0.900 0.918 0.918 1.022 3 Wearing Apparel 6 6 13 0.900 1.100 0.900 0.479 0.479 0.802 3 Leather 2 2 14 0.900 1.100 0.900 1.007 1.007 1.066 3 Paper 16 16 22 0.900 1.100 0.900 0.967 0.967 0.734 3 Chemicals 12 12 19 0.960 1.100 0.960 0.903 0.903 0.702 3 Rubber 13 13 18 0.960 1.100 0.960 1.026 1.026 0.763 3 Non-MetalMinera 25 25 16 0.901 1.100 0.901 1.152 1.152 0.826 3 Imnand Steel 14 14 13 0.740 1.100 0.740 0.931 0.931 0.716 3 Non-FerrousMeL 14 14 20 0.740 1.100 0.740 0.825 0.825 0.663 3 Wocd&Metals 9 9 14 0.811 0.811 0.811 0.888 0.888 0.594 3 Non-Electr. Mach. 8 8 9 0.740 0.740 0.740 1.012 1.012 0.694 3 ElectricalMachin 8 8 28 0.740 0.740 0.740 1.035 1.035 0.705 3 Transp. Equip. 10 10 27 0.867 0.867 0.867 0.982 0.982 0.679 3 Other Manufacture 9 9 12 0.740 0.740 0.740 0.550 0.550 0.463 3 Constnrction 0 0 0 0.900 0.500 0.900 1.500 1.500 1.200 3 Electricity 0 0 0 0.521 0.300 0.521 1.200 1.500 1.300 0.5 Commerce 0 0 0 0.800 0.300 0.800 1.500 1.300 1.200 3 Trans.& Comm. 0 0 0 0.502 0.300 0.502 1.100 1.200 1.400 3 Financc&lnsur. 0 0 0 0.800 0.800 0.800 1.500 1.200 1.100 3 OtherServices 0 0 0 0.800 0.800 0.800 1.300 1.100 1.200 3 Source: Roland-Holst, Reinert, and Shiells (1994, p. 67); last column adapted from GREEN (Bumiaux er a1. 1992). 142 4.2. Em place bc accompl available evaluatic This is c Third, fi constitutl 0f consur comm intemahz the GMT] “I“ The avfiilabilil (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6‘) (7) 4.2. Environmental Components The integration of an environmental component into economic modeling needs to take place bofin on fine production side as well as on fine side of fine environmental extemality. To accomplish such integration, ideally filree (quantitative) information components should be available. First, emissions of each sector need to be krnown. This information allows fine evaluation of sectoral changes on emission levels. Second, an abatement function is needed This is crucial for evaluating fine impact of regulations on fine cost structure of various sectors. Third, fine emissions extemalities should be included In is simplest fornn, an extemality constitutes a pure welfare reduction. In finis case, fine extemality does not affect fine production orconsumptiornpattems offine economy and remains externaltofineecononnicrrnodel itself. By contrast, if emissiorns affect certain production or consumption factors, finis impact needs to be intemalized into fine model. Unfortunately, fine data situation is not such finat fine relationslnips of fine environmental component can be easily constructed Ten steps are necessary for establishing fine full economy-environment relationship for fine Norfin American Free Trade area. These steps follow a combination of logical and practical reasons, especially limited data availability. (1) Derivation of fine sectoral emission coefficiens (available only for fine U.S.). (2) Derivation of sectoral abatement coss (available only for fine U.S.). (3) Construction of fine abatement function. (4) Extrapolation of U.S. relationships to finose of fine ofiner two NAFTA countries. (5) Calculation of total emissions for each country. (6) Association of emission values wifin ambient pollution levels. (7) Establishing fine effect of pollution on human healfin. 143 additio criteria ernviror 4.2.1. 5 States. fine Wo work i] Agency the the, Well re: Frommc Donutam by POUu (8) Calculation of fine degree to which healfin limis labor as a production factor. (9) Quantification of total welfare effect. ' (10) Political income elasticity of pollution abatement In fine following sections each of finese eight individual steps will be addressed in turn Irn addition, one could list fine choice of fine pollutant(s) included in fine analysis as an important criterion It will become clear finat a whole set of uncertainties is involved in constructing fine environmental data These uncertainties stress fine experimental nature of finis paper. 4.2.1. Sectoral Emission Coefficients in the United States The first task involves taking stock of fine sectoral information that exists for fine United States. Sectoral emission values draw heavily on fine work undertaken wifinin fine framework of fine World Bank’s Industrial Pollution Projection System (IPPS; see Hettige et al. 1995). This work, in turn, is indebted to fine Toxic Release Inventory of fine U. S. Environmental Protection Agency. The IPPS liss various air, land and water pollution emissions for industrial sectors at fine finree-digit level. The main interest of finis paper is in air pollutans, because finey have fairly well researched damage functions. Air pollution tends to spread over large areas, and protection from is hazardous efi‘ecs is difiicult and cosfiy. By contrast, land and water pollutans are generally of a local nature. This concentration means also finat damages caused by pollution of finese two media cannot be generalized because finey are highly location dependent and can often be avoided or abated. In fine extreme, a polluted area could simply be roped off. Major air pollutans included in fine IPPS are 802, N02, CO, total particulate matter (TP), particles smaller finan 10 microns (PMlO), and volatile organic compounds (V 0C). Table 4-9 liss fine toxic release coefiiciens as a function of sectoral value added. Data are adjusted to 144 other sen For elec OECD 1 source 6 emission match fine disaggregation into 26 sectors used so far. Since fine IPPS database only contains dasmmmufactunngsecmw,itisnecesseymconsfiuedasforfineofinesectos.The followirng adjustmens are made: Emissions for agriculture are set to zero. Mining is assumed to have halffine emission intensity of non-metal minerals. Construction is given equal values to finose of fine wood and metal sector. Ennission values for commerce, finance and insurance, and other services are set equal to fine lowest values assigrned to any of fine manufacturirng sectors. For electricity production and transport, fine values are calibrated such finat finey replicated OECD (1995) emission figures.23 Because fine United States constitutes fine original data sonnce for fine constructing fine IPPS data, fine assumption finat finese values reflect sectoral enissicrn averages for fine United States is unproblematic. ’3 Values for electricity are calibrated to constitute for 802 69% oftotal enissions; for N02 22%; CO 5%; VOC 20%, and particles 20%. The analogous enission allocation for transport is for $02 4% , for N02 31%, for CO 80%, VOC 40 "/6, and for particles 25%. It is assumed that 40 percent of transport is commercial transport. Emissions for private transport and household ernissicns are not incorporated into these figures. 145 Table Sector Table 4-9: Pollution intensity of the production sectors (pounds per USD million value added) Sector 802 N02 CO Volatile Fine Total Toxicity Organic Particul- Sus- Weigh- Com- ates pended ted Index pounds (PM10) Particu- (V OC) lates ([811 Agriculture 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Mirning 26259 177 3015 855 21555 17024 619 Petroleum 82270 48716 41302 32495 1441 16012 751 Food Processing 61 15 4548 1653 1406 2328 . 5563 202 Beverages 3893 1881 212 7588 97 294 29 Tobacco 1840 1113 145 366 14 34 5 Textiles 1948 1637 495 3000 29 736 35 Wearing Apparel 1 105 289 94 2602 31 370 18 Leafiner l 105 289 94 2602 31 370 18 Paper 13290 7801 15060 3018 740 2583 123 Chemicals 7443 8115 15628 7318 529 1535 94 Rubber 2412 831 104 3083 42 275 18 Non-Metal Minerals 52518 35517 6030 1711 43110 34049 1239 Iron and Steel 41044 17829 63961 5494 11344 9510 425 Non-Ferrous Metals 123489 4022 57444 4492 1135 10371 460 Wood & Metals 1 199 1702 3454 4704 487 2303 92 Non-Electr. Mach 1894 801 1876 1499 2 356 18 Electrical Machines 1158 551 684 815 5 122 8 Trarnsport Equipment 3082 1301 410 6427 129 913 47 Ofiner Manufactures 1 12 200 42 737 25 77 4 Cornstruction 1 199 1702 3454 4704 487 2303 92 Electricity 362087 343 75 30440 3 1647 6929 14727 797 Commerce 1 12 200 42 366 3 34 2 Trarnsp. & Comm. 6712 15490 155758 20241 2770 5887 377 Finance & Insurance 112 200 42 366 3 34 2 Ofiner Services 1 12 200 42 366 3 34 2 Source: Adapted from IPPS, March 1995; Based on OECD figures (Environmental Data 1995). For fine toxicity weight fine shares are assumed to be 70 % for TSP, and 7.5 % for all ofiner except PM10, which is set to zero to avoid double counting. 146 thecross< TSPconst N02 form choice Of ; and VOC reportton The model will focus on TSP, as will be explained furfiner below. Table 4-10 presents the cross correlation of various sectoral emission indicators to provide a simple test whether TSP constitutes a good approximation of a larger pollution problem: TSP, toxicity, mm and N02 fornn a close cluster. This close clustering is particularly true for fine correlation of the logarithmic values, which assignns less weight to fine extreme values. Wifinin this group, the choice of an indicator is relatively easy. By contrast, the correlation of fine first cluster wifin C0 and VOC emission factors is relatively low. SO; takes an intermediate position Chapter 5 will report to what degree the results depend on the choice of fine pollutant. Table 4-10: Correlation matrix of various sectoral emission parameters (logarithmic in italics) TSP TOX PM10 N02 S02 C0 VOC TSP 1.000 0.982 0.890 0.832 0.474 0.233 0.346 TOX 0.994 1.000 0.809 0.896 0.594 0.348 0.504 PMIO 0.939 0.947 1.000 0.574 0.194 0.044 -0.027 N02 0.902 0.934 0. 900 1.000 0.596 0.373 0.746 SO; 0.877 0.910 0. 824 0.906 1.000 0.225 0.682 CO 0.853 0.874 0. 776 0.874 0.824 1.000 0.534 VOC 0. 6 74 0. 705 0. 5 73 0. 660 0.678 0. 706 1.000 4.2.2. Sectoral Abatement Costs in the United States Information on abatement expenditures of manufacturing sectors in fine U.S. is available from Low (1992) who compiled data of fine U.S. Department of Commerce (1988a; 1988b). The first column of Table 4-11 lists sectoral abatement values. Similarly to fine situatiorn for emissions, values are set to zero for agriculture. For commerce, finance and insurance, and other services, values are assumed to be a finird lower finan finose of fine next lowest manufacturing sector, paper. They are set to 0.1 percent of production value. Following an 147 arcsettc of total ; than one hardly ju to under: Fir upendin drag on I dealing v losses in profis d; Sec expmdm Control is Therefme pmducfion estimate by fine European Commission (1994), abatement costs of electricity production zero are set to 9 percent of production costs. The data result in relatively small costs of environmental abatement of only 0.6 percent of total production costs on average. Most manufacturing sectors face abatement costs of less finarn one finird of one percent of production costs. The figures appear implausibly low and could hardly justify a discussion on fine trade impact of environmental regulation The data are certain to underestimate actual regulatory costs by one half. First, even if it were possible to determine wifin precision fine level of physical expenditures on environmental abatement, finey would neglect fine fact finat fine environmental drag on businesses includes a large number of intangible factors. These are resources spent dealing wifin administrative procedures, costs of government inspections, uncertainty arnd time losses in waiting for permits, risks of litigation, etc. For instance, Gray and Shadbegian (1993) estimate that, for every dollar finat appears in a company’s books on emission reduction, actual profits drop by roughly 3 to 4 dollars, wifin some variation among sectors. Second, fine data listed in fine first column of fine Table are only based on finose expenditures finat serve exclusively fine purpose of pollution abatement. However, ennissicns control is increasingly integrated into production equipment and production processes. Therefore, it is difficult to separate statistically what is purely productive expenditure arnd what production component serves environmental purposes. 148 Table 4-11: Derivation of abatement expenditures for United States in 1988 Sector abatement total adjusted Adjusted total Domestic costs (% of abatement abatement abate ent production production)!» costs n costs (% of costs6 (bn USD)” USD) production)d) Agriculture 195.49 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Mining 24.97 1.50 0.37 3.33 0.83 Petroleum 187.68 1.53 2.87 3.40 6.37 Food Processirng 298.41 0.33 0.98 0.73 2.19 Beverages 49.45 0.33 0.16 0.73 0.36 Tobacco 31.06 0.16 0.05 0.36 0.11 Textiles 86.59 0.27 0.23 0.60 0.52 Wearing Apparel 62. 58 0.27 0.17 0.60 0.38 Leafiner 8.55 0.24 0.02 0.53 0.05 Paper 210.67 0.14 0.29 0.31 0.65 Chemicals 199.16 1.18 2.35 2.62 5.22 Rubber 122.34 0.30 0.37 0.67 0.81 Non-Metal Mineral 64.92 0.70 0.45 1.55 1.01 Iron and Steel 73.67 1.21 0.89 2.69 1.98 Non-Ferrous Metal 69.92 0.48 0.34 1.07 0.75 Wood & Metals 268.40 0.32 0.86 0.71 1.91 Non-Electr. Mach. 157.25 0.18 0.28 0.40 0.63 Electrical Machines 291.74 0.35 1.02 0.78 2.27 Transport Equip. 312.24 0.28 0.87 0.62 1.94 Ofirer Marnufactures 91.91 0.22 0.20 0.49 0.45 Construction 594.58 0.30 1.78 0.67 3.96 Electricity 272.89 9.00 24.56 19.98 54.52 Commerce 869.94 0.10 0. 87 0.22 1.93 Trarnsp. & Comm. 391.82 1.48 5.80 3.29 12.88 Finance & Insur. 1114.47 0.10 1.11 0.22 2.47 Other Services 2143.40 0.10 2.14 0.22 4.76 TOTAL 8194.09 0.60 49.07 1.33 108.94 Source: a) Social accounting matrix of Reinert et al. (1992); b) Low (1992), Electric derived fiom European Commission (1994); costs for services are adapted from Rutledge arnd Vegan (1994): It is assumed finat business abatement of mobile ennissions can be attributed to transport and commurricatiorns. Services, transport and communications, finance arnd insurance, and ofiners are assumed to have abatement expenditures of 0.1 percent in raw expenditures, which is somewhat lower finan fine lowest manufacturing sector. c) = column a) times colurrnrn b); d) and e) own calculations as described in text. See also Footnote 9. 149 En! provided the regul of finese t An embodie data sou (Rutledg (camam over 50‘] file Sartre mm, PTOducu" Environmental drag and fine statistical underestimation justify finat fine raw figures provided by Low should be adjusted upwards. In particular, in light of fine purpose of assessing fine regulatory impact of difi‘ering regulations on trade determination, an urncritical acceptance of finese data would prejudge fine analytical outcome. An' ad hoc assessment of fine order of magnitude to which environmental costs are embodied in production costs is possible by going back to original Departrrnent of Commerce data source finat was used by Low and are summarized in fine Survey of Current Business (Rutledge arnd Vogan 1994). Between 1975 and 1992, total annual pollutiorn abatenent irn (constant 1987 dollars) increased from USD billion 57 to 87, denoting an irncrease of slighfiy over 50 percentThe data report an increase in capital expenditures by only 20 percent during fine same time span“ This small increase reflects fine statistical phenomenon of an irncreasirng integration of pollution control into fine equipment, which finer can no longer be separated fi'om productive investment. Therefore, fine reported data on current expenditure are likely to be a better approximation for fine time trend of pollution abatement, because fine technological integratiorn of abatement afi‘ects finem less. From 1975 until 1992, finese figures increased from $17.1 billion to 38.7 billion, marking an increase by 126 percent” Ifone applies firis growfin rate to capital expenditures in fine 1975 (to net out statistical shtinkttge) one yields an adjusted 1992 figure for total abatement expenditures of S 131 billion instead of fine $87 billion reported by 2‘ The more relevant figure for our purposes would have been the depreciation of capital equipment torcflectthecxisting stock, ratherthanthefigurcs fornew investment. 150 percent t expendit abatemei business Rutledge and Vogan. For fine base year of fine NAFTA calculations 1988, fire value is $109 billion. This figure represents 6.3 percent of fine United States profits in finat year, or 1.33 percent of GDP. The values for abatement expenditures finat are reported by Low are firerefore annualized to yield costs of that level (finird column of Table 4.11)."5 In fine model, finese expenditures are assumed to burden only production factor capital and are used to calculate abatement capital (164).” They are unlikely to overestimate fine gross costs imposed on businesses.” In addition, fine figures leave out fine significant share of abatement costs finat accrue to households and govemment directly. This onnission needs to be borne in mind when interpreting fine simulation results. However, fine trade incidence of private arnd public abatement costs would be less pronounced finan finOse of producer abatement costs. Only finose costs finat are linked directly to fine production process will substantially afi‘ect fine locatiorn of industries. This impact on sectoral competitiveness does not exist if abatement costs are borne by ofiner econonnic actors. However, evidenfiy fine financial extemality afi‘ects fine overall 2‘ Expenditures on motor vehicle enission abatencnt are subtracted, because of an interruption of the series. 3‘ The values by Low (1992) present only pollution abatennent operating costs, which excludes investment. Therefore, the adjustments in fire table are higher finan the calculation would suggest. Raw expenditures data are adjusted to yield total expenditures of 109 billion, i.e., multiplied by 2.22. This figure excludes about 1/3 of enission abatement, because it occurs within private consumption, i.e., private transport, heating, etc. ’7 In economic terms, this exclusive burdening of capital takes place, even ifthe abatenerrt itself usesonlylaborasaninput.lnfiniscasc,theassociatedwagccostsreducethcfactorrewardof capiml.Cmcepmafly,hdoenamafiewhethewemEgimthepmcesasomofamduccdme ofretumforaconstantcapitalstock,orasoneofaconstantrateofreturnforarcduccdcapital stock. 2'Howevcr,theyovcrestimatethenetcosts,i.e.whenthebenefitofrcduccdexternalitiesis considered. 151 economy: Costs that are borne by fine consumers of certain products will afi'ect consumption patterns. Pollution abatement undertaken by fine government also affects fine competitiveness of firms indirecfiy via an increased tax burden to finance fine expenditure. 4.2.3. Abatement Functions Information on abatement expenditure and fine amount of ennissions in each sector does not establish a relationship between fine two parameters. The construction of an abatement function deals wifin two dimculties. First, little systematic information is available finat could be used to construct sectoral abatement functions. Estimations by Hartrnran et a1. (1997) are statistically not robust enough to be a base for sectorally differentiated abatement fnrrnctions. Since fine expenditure data do not allow a sectoral differentiation of fine abatement cost furnction it must be assumed finat a macroeconorrnically established relationship holds for each irndividual SOCIDI'. Second, it is not evident which part of fire abatement costs should be attributed to which pollutant, because. cleaner technology often reduces emissions for multiple pollutarnts. For instance, a technology that reduces fuel consumption reduces CO; emissions as well as emissions in particles, sulfur oxides, etc. Therefore a large component of joint costs make it practical to look at abatement costs and emissions in fireir entirety. A practical approach is to use a pollution index to reflect fine cumulative benefits of all abatement efl‘orts. The nnodel uses two difl‘erent indices. One is to only trace fine development in particles, which already irncludes a variety of molecules, so finat it correlates fairly well wifin ofiner air pollutants. In addition, fine impact of particles on healfin is statistically well established. For a sensitivity arnalysis, a pollution index based on toxicity weights will be used. 152 1n 1i; dawn U.S. time air emiss: Emission: reporting fimwm period 1 C02 em Thel In liglnt of fine poor data quality, finis paper applies a simple approach for fine construction of an abatement function based on aggregate ennissions and abatement figures. To finis end, U.S. time-series data on abatement expenditure from 1975 to 199229 are set into relation wifin air ennission data during fine same period (OECD 1989, and 1995-Environmental Data). Ennissions of particulates (PM10) for all sources inn fine United States sank by one finird for fine reporting period fi'om 1975 until 1992 (Table 4-12). Emissions of ofiner pollutants sank during fine same time by similar orders of magnitude, alfinough finere is some variation in fine trend across pollutants. CO and 80;: and VOC emissions decrease by 17 to 36 percent during fine period However, NOx emissions actually increase during this time period, in parallel wifin C02 emissions. Table 4-12: Pollution abatement expenditures and air emissions in the United States . , . 1975 1992 Change (%) Abatement expending?" $58.1 bn $131.6 bn 126.18 C02-Emissions (1%? 4800 ' 5035 4.90 PM10 (1000 ton)? 10600 7080 -3321 CO (1000 tons) 124731 79092 -36.59 NOx (1000 tons)? 20100 21001 4.48 sox (1000 tons) ) 26000 20622 -20.68 voc (1000 tons)” 25000 20617 .1753 Average pollutants (excl. C02)? . -20.71 Avegge (gdjusted for growfin) ) -25.60 Source: 8) Adjusted from Rudlege and Vogan (1994); b) OECD-Environmental Data (1989 1995); c) arifinmetic average of change for CO, PM10, NOx, 80K and VOC; d) previous row minus growfin in C02. '9 The longest time span for which bofin enission arnd abatement figures are available. 153 Ho»- neural ab: factors 11: economic intensive technolog a more c these finr emission 0f fuel c1 Fn emission by 4.9 p the net e by 25.6 90111160, in the ( 1992), , undena] Pine .3 Econo However, finese trends in abatement expenditures and in ennissions do not establish an actual abatement relationship. In parallel to fine decomposition of fine pollution efl‘ects, finree factors need to be taken into account when assessing fine importance of abatement. first, economic growth (scale effect); second, a shift in fine industrial structure away from emission- intersive industry towards generally cleaner services (composition effect); and finally, technological progress, reducing fine need for material finrouglnput (techrnology efl‘ect). Short of a nrore complicated analysis, fine consumption of hydrocarbons can be taken as a proxy for finese finree combined factors. This approach is also likely to be consistent wifin fine way ennissions data tend to be constructed in practice, wifin total ennissions output set as a multiple of fuel cornsumption. From 1975 to 1992, C02 emissions rose by 4.9 percent (OECD 1995). Therefore, had emission technology stayed fire same, one could have expected ofirer emissions to rise similarly by 4.9 percent Instead, finey fell on average by 20.7 percent One might finerefore assume finat fine net efi‘ect of fine 126 percent increase in abatement expenditure30 is a decrease irn emissions by 25.6 percent (20.7 % direct reduction plus 4.9% C02 trend). This value translates into a pollution-abatement substitution elasticity of 0.36. The value lies within fine range finat is given in fine OECD literature review for energy-capital elasticity of substitution (Bunniaux et al. 1992), and is taken as a central estimate for fine model simulations. A sensitivity nun will be undertaken wifin a value of 0.6 which results fiom making an analogous calculation based on PM10 ennissions. 3oEconornicgowthandtechnicalprogressinabatementappeartoberoughlyinbalancc. 154 specificini concernsfi model 8551 However, expenditu 4.2.4. Ex Iti not GXist adjusted mung-yr: light of 1 An important implicit assumption of this approach is finat finis relationship holds across all sectors. There is no particular rationale for finis assumption; however, given fine lack of nnore specific informatien, fine described mefinodology needs to serve as a proxy. A special problen concerns fine treatment of fine abatement elasticity in fine presence of scale elasticity. Here fine nnodel assumes finat scale economies apply only to production inputs labor and capital.31 This means finat pollution output will rise more finan proportional to fine irnputs of capital and labor. However, as a consequence, firere are econonnies of scale wifin respect to abatement expenditures. 4.2.4. Extension of Environmental Relationships to Canada and Mexico It is not possible to estimate parameters for the ofiner two countries analogous to fine environmental sink function of fine U. S., because independent and consistent data sources do not exist in particular for Mexico (arnd to a lesser extent for Canada). Irnstead, fine U.S. data are adjusted to fine situation in fine ofiner countries. For Canada, fine hypofinesis is simply finat fine country’s emissions factors and abatement expenditures are identical to those of fine US. In light of Mexico’s completely difl‘erent developmental status, finis hypofinesis is not defensible. Following fine argument made in fine previous section, wifin identical emission techrnology per nrrnit of capital employed, pollution output in Mexico should be proportional to fine consumptiorn of energy. Because energy cornsumption in fine U.S. is 16.8 times higher finan that of Mexico in fine base year (OECD 1998), emissions in fine U.S. would be higher finan Mexican 3' Pollution follows fire formula: pouutiona fi, 2 abate, 2 Z, 2 76) = 2““ pollutionCKF, abate, Z, '15) . 155 emissions by exactly that factor. However, actual emissions for fine U.S. are only between 2 and 10 times higher finan finose for Mexico.32 If one takes a simple average of fine figures for 802, NOx, CO, and VOC, Mexican production is 3 times as polluting per output value as fine US. Assuming a constant abatement elasticity of 0.36, we can conclude finat abatement expenditure in Mexico is 5 percent of finat in fine United States per unit of production If one assumes an elasticity of 0.6, Mexican abatement would be 15.5 percent finose of fine U.S. per unit of production Table 4-13: Pollution output in United States, Mexico, and Canada US Mexico Canada Ratios US/MX Value Add 566.2 43.3 78.4 13.08 Gross production 391.8 17.7 64.8 22.16 802 842 403 95 2.09 NOx 9718 955 1223 10.18 CO 81025 17152 7164 4.72 VOC/HC 10650 1753 908 6.08 Source: OECD-Environmental Data (1989 1995) Alternatively, a set of ennissiorns data for 14 sectors in Mexico would be available (varn Torngeren et al. 1991). This is not used due to an apparent gap in fire data quality and a limited sectoral breakdown of fine emission figures. In any case, for finis study fine relative change in fine level of ennissions is more important finan fine absolute level of pollution. Table 4—14 correlates fine TSP per value added and abatement costs per unit of output wifin fire capital-labor ratios and net export positions of each country. As a first impression nnost correlations are rafiner low. The highest positive correlation consists between pollution and 3’ Values for PM have not been used, because of differences in measurement techniques. 156 abatement. However, there are some hints that the relationship fits less for sectors with extreme values, as can be derived from the fact that the logarithmic correlation is substantially better thanthelinearone. Table 4-14: Correlation matrix of various sectoral parameters (logarithmic in Italics) TSP Abate- K/L- KIL- K/L- Net Net Net ment ratio ratio ratio exports exports exports USA Canada Mexico US Canada Mexico TSP 1.000 0.305 0.149 0.284 0.264 0.078 0.092 0.083 Abatement 0.789 1.000 -0.069 0.052 -0.117 -0.042 0.121 0.017 K/L-ratio USA -0. 039 -0. 237 1.000 0.710 0.549 -0.280 0.295 0.131 K/L-ratio Canada 0.246 0.101 0. 601 1.000 0.218 -0.080 0.190 0.106 K/L-ratio Mexico 0.161 -0. 058 0.460 0.147 1.000 -0.425 0.404 0.173 Net exports US 0.002 0. 015 -0.102 -0. 069 -0. 286 1.000 -0.861 -0.490 Net exports Canada 0.177 0.051 0.120 0.197 0.260 -0.861 1.000 0.601 Net exports Mexico 0.023 0.071 0.098 0.109 0.111 -0. 490 0. 601 1.000 Note: a) Since for net exports no logarithms could be calculated, their original values are used also in tlne logarithmic correlation. b) For net trade an index is constructed by forming tlne ratio of net intra-NAFI' A trade and domestic production Pollution intensity tends to be positively correlated with capital intensity, although tlne logaritlnnnic correlation for the U.S. is slightly negative. By contrast, tlne sign of tlne relationship between abatement expenditure and capital intensity is mixed, with a negative sign for the U.S. and Canada, and a positive one for Mexico. The relationslnip of abatement and pollution intensity to net export positions is practically zero.33 33’Itmayappenrinconsistentthatalltlnreecor'relations forthetradeindexarepositivealthough intra-NAFI‘ A net exports cancel out by definition. However, the use of a trade index (net exports divided by output) enn result in a statistical paradox, if countries difi‘er in size. For instance, if Mexico has a trade surplus of 10 with the US, the index values for Mexico would be 0.2 and for the U.S. -0.001, ifproduction in Mexico is 50 and in the U.S. is 1000. 157 The table also shows another example of fine Leontief-Paradox, as it shows that fine U.S. is importing capital-intensive goods. However, as was explained furfiner up, finis finding is consistent wifin fine statistical results finat establish fine U.S. as a relatively labor-intesive country. By contrast, bofin Mexico and Canada are exporters of goods that are relatively capital-intensive. This fact, again, is in line wifin fine findings of fineir relative endewtnents. 4.2.5. Calculation of Total Emissions Technically, the calculation of total emissions is straightforward It consists simply of multiplying fine sectoral ennission values just discussed by fine sectoral estimates of value added These figures are finen summed over all sectors. However, for electricity and trarnsport no emission factors per nnnit of output are available. Instead, these ennission factors are calibrated for the U.S. to reflect total emission estimates for fine respective shares of road trarnsport arnd electricity production. This mefinod implies that for finese cases total annd sectoral enissions had to be calculated simultaneously. The values finus calculated for the United States are used directly for fine ofiner two countries without making any furtlner adjustments. 4.2.6. Relationship of Total Emissions to Air Quality I Of fine multitude of air pollutants, finis paper imputes only fine consequences of srrnall particles. Despite considerable remaining uncertainties, small particles are fine air pollutant for which fine efi‘ect on healfin is best researched due to broadly available statistics. Furfinermore, fine relationship between particulate emissions, air quality and healfin fits very well a linear fnmction, which is not fine case for more reactive pollutants such as NOx or ozone. This means finat a doubling irn emissionns has a doubling of particle concentrations as a consequence. A linear relationship also holds for fine effect of air quality on human healfin. For many ofine pollutants, one can discern a threshold effect: a concentration in fine air below a certain value 158 does not entail any measurable impact on human healfin, while higher concentratiorns can have cornsiderable consequences. These non-linearities would not allow a simple aggregation, as it is possible for particles. However, even particles are not wifinout measurement problems. Notably, finey do not constitute a single molecule, but are composed by a group of molecules, ranging from simple dust to 80x. It is now well established finat fine damaging efl‘ect of particles on respiratory fnnnctions is fine greater fine smaller fine individual particles are, because smaller particles enter fine lungs rrnore deeply finan bigger ones. This insight leads to a variety of measurements difl‘ering by fine size of particles included. They range from total suspended particles (TSP) to particles fine size of 10 microns (PM10) to particles fine size of 2.5 rrnicrons (PM2.5) or even smaller. A generally accepted relationship is to assume finat PM2.5 constitutes half of PM10, which in turn constitutes half of TSP. For fine United States, using fine average exposure, PM 2.5 lies roughly at 18ug/m3 (Dockery er al. 1993; American Lung Association 1995). The same concentration is assumed for Canada. For Mexico, fine derivation of concentration levels of total suspended particles follows Ronnieu, Weitzenfeld and Finkelman (1990). Average exposure of . total suspended particles lies at 141 ug/m3. In applying fine approximation finat one quarter of fine TSP is PM2.5,34 fine average population in Mexico is exposed to a PM2.5 level 35.3 ug/m3. Definite extremely high levels of exposure in some districts of Mexico city (reaching average TSP exposure of up to 500 pig/m3) cautious calculations result in an average exposure to air ”Thislatioisacautiousestimate,asinfineUnitedStatestheratioisnearlyoneinthree. 159 pollutantsfinatisonlytwiceashighasfinatoffineUS.”Aonepercentreductioninennissiorns reduces PM2.5 concentration in the U.S. by 0.018ug/m3 and in Mexico by 0.0353 rig/m3. However, it is likely finat fine values for Mexico err at fine side of cautiorn, and finere is evidence finat fine actual risk of exposure to PM2.5 may be higher finan fine numbers suggest. FirstfineratioofPMthoTSPinfineUS. sarnplesiscloserto3finanto4.Thereisno evidence finat fine ratio in Mexico should be higher. Collins and Scott (1993) cite evidence finat fine geographical situation of Mexico City is very conducive to fine formation of vey fine particles. Despite considerable dificulties in fine reliability of measurements particle exposure appears to be at least eight times fine levels detected in Chicago. Secornd, due to substantial difi'erencesinwealfinbetweenfineNorfin andfine SoufinoffineNAFTAareeitisliltelyfinat Mexicans are less able to protect finemselves against particle exposure finan Canadians or U.S. 4.2.7. Health Effect of Air Quality There exist a substantial number of epidemiological studies measuring fine impact of particles on various indices of human healfin. These concern inter alia premature mortality; chronic bronclnitis in adults; respiratory hospital adrnissiorns; emergency room visits; asfinnna symptom days; days wifin respiratory symptoms; acute bronchitis in children; restricted activity days, etc. (American Lung Association 1995) These are dificult to aggregate, since they contain substantial double counting. Most interesting and straightforward to interpret for purposes of 3’ The average level of total suspended particles in Mexico city (38 °/o of population) lies at around 250 mg/m’, those for other cities (38 percent) is assumed to be 125 mym3, and for rural areas 25 160 economic modeling are restricted activity days or work loss. Ostro (1987) estimates finat an increase in ambient concentrations of fine particles (PM2.5) by 1 mg/m3 leads to 0.403 additional annual restricted activity days per worker. The estimate might overestimate fine isolated efi’ect finat particulates have on humarn healfin, because fine econometric estimate by Ostro is likely to have captured also fine efi‘ect of ofiner pollutants, which are probably closely related to particulate pollution However, fine estimate will underestirrnate fine healfin efl‘ect of total air pollutiorn. In additiorn, fine air pollution damage function neglects non-healfin-related extemalities, such as fine pollution of environmental media like soil and water, and omits damages to plants and materials. Wifin certain caveats attached, fine functional form can be used as an approximation of fine healfin efi‘ects of pollution. Ronnieu, Weitzenfeld, and Finkelman (1990) have applied finis mefinod to pollution in Mexico city. 4.2.8. Effect of Health on Labor Productivity TheworklossestimatesofOsfiocanbeusedinastraightforwardfashiontomeasure reduced labor output due to particulate emissions. This implies finat a reduction in pollution by 10 percent would reduce annually sick days in fine U.S. by 0.725 days, and would increase labor supply by 0.29 percent”. Identical figures are assumed for Canada For Mexico, a ten percent reduction in air pollution leads to an increase in activity days by 1.42 days or 0.57 percent. It could be argued in particular for fine case of Mexico finat not all sick workers stay mg/m’. If one quarter of these values consists fine particles (<2.5 mg/m3), fine average population in Mexico is exposed to a PM 2.5 level 31.5 mg/m’. 3‘ This is the equivalent of 0.725 sick days/250 work days per annum. 161 away from work However, in any case, fineir productivity will be lower, and it can be argued finat lack of treatment probably leads to a more drawn-out disease. For purposes of a sensitivity analysis, fine emission values of fine toxicity-weighted index will be used Following fine calculations of the European Comnnission, total particulates cause only 70 percent of fine total healfin damage of air pollution Therefore, in finis case, fine healfin efi‘ects are increased accordingly by 43 percent” over finose of fine case taking into acconnnt only particulates. 4.2.9. Welfare Effect or Pollution While the use of fine equation for work loss is likely to be a sufl'rcient proxy for measuring fine efi‘ect of fine air pollution extemality on labor productivity, finis factor underestimates fine total welfare impact of pollution. Most notably it omits fine impact of pollution on premature mortality. According fine American Lung Association (1995) fire cost of finis factor is at least as high as fine costs of morbidity. Therefore, a cautious adjustment is to assume finat fine welfare costs due to air pollution are double those for fine work loss. This welfare component does not affect any ofiner component of fine model. 4.2.10. Political Income Elasticity for Pollution Abatement The income elasticity for pollution abatement (s) is not fixed Variations in finis parameter will be used to determine fine sensitivity of fine model simulations to fine inclusiorn of finis parameter. However, a central rate of 0.75 is assumed. This is based on two plausibility 3’ 43% = (l-70%)/70%. 162 considerations. First, based on purchasing power parity, fine U.S. is 3.73 times as rich as Mexico ($19,851/35,323). Iffine assumption is correct finat Mexico allows roughly finree times fine amournt of pollution per unit of output, finis implies an income elasticity of regulation 0. 83 (3.73”'“=o.33). Second, if fine value were one or larger, it would mean finat, in practice, pollution would be nnnlikely to ever become a problem in any country over its whole development pafin This cannot be squared wifin the empirical observation of the inverted U-shaped pollution cnnrve. By contrast, a somewhat lower value is compatible wifin fine observed curve, if it is accompanied by fine typical structural changes finat occur during a country’s development process. During an early development phase, a rising pollution level will accompany fine economic specialization inn fine relatively dirty secondary sector. During a later development phase, a falling pollution level will accompany fine growfin of fine relatively clean tertiary sector. Iffine elasticity were too low, only a steady increase in pollution would be observed, except in fine case where dirty production shrinks not only in relative but also in absolute terms. 163 CHAPTERS SIMULATION RESULTS This chapter presents fine results of simulations wifin ETERNA A first section proceeds by building up fine full model in several steps. It starts by describing fine sirnnulation results of fine trade liberalization scenario wifin nationally fixed capital stock excluding any environmental interactions. The basic model is presented in two variants. Tlne model is finer extended to include fine environmental extemality. A second extension incorporates in addition induced regulation effects. Section 2 modifies fine policy scenario of fine first section by allowing intra- NAFTA capital mobility. Togefiner wifin fine first scenario, firis scenario serves as reference case to assess fine importance of various assumptions. Section 3 shows fine importance of fine petroleum sector in determining fine results. Section 4 presents sensitivity nnns on a numbe of calibration parameters. A fifth section analyzes different formulations of fine country trarnsforrnation equation. Section 6 illustrates fine impact of unilateral actions inn NAFTA countries. A final section presents a synopsis of fine results and provides indicative cornclusions. 5.1. Building up the Model Structure of the Central Case 5.1.1. Simple Trade Scenario with Internationally Immobile Capital mm To allow an understanding of fine model mechanism it is useful to start wifin a simulation for which fine environmental component is completely switched 03. The underlyirng policy 164 assumption is that trade barriers disappear for all intro-NAFTA trade.” The efi‘ects of reducing tarifl‘ arnd non-tariff barriers are quite distinct. Tarifl‘s cornstitute bofin costs for irnportes and revenues for governments. To compensate for clnanges in revenues governments adjust fine transfers to households. By contrast, fine production of fine public good and all tax rates, apart from tarifi's remain constant For non-tarifi‘ barriers, no compensation mecharnism exists. By assumption, non-tarifl' barriers cornstitnrte a waste of resources finat are used for rent seeking A reduction in non-tariff barriers makes finese resources available for final consumption or immediate production. Therefore, even wifirout any changes in import volumes, fine ecornonnies benefit from fine increase in net output. By contrast, a tarifi‘ reduction leads to economic growfin and irncreased welfare only because trade patterns adjust to reduced distortions. M mi im The macroeconomic impact of fine trade liberalization is listed in Table 5-1. All figures express percentage changes from the pre-NAFI‘ A baseline. An evident efl‘ect is finat bofin fine absolute and relative trade integration of Norfin America increases, as fine strong rise in trade volume attests.39 In terms of aggregate economic indicators, NAFTA has a positive impact on fine North American econorrnies. In relative terms, fine greatest winners of fine free trade agreement are Canada and Mexico, which realize GDP gains by roughly 2.5 % each The irncrease in fine USA is 0.67 °/o. This relative distribution of gains results fiom fine difi‘erences in 3' In fine following the term NAFTA will be used, although fine trade liberalimtion modeled propely also includes the earlier Canadian American Free Trade Agreenent (CAFT A). 165 size and dependency of fine finree courntries. However, in absolute terms, fine U.S. is fine main beneficiary. Out of a total gain of S41 bn, slightly less finan two-finirds ($25.7 bn) takes place in fine U.S., Canada enjoys a quarter of fine benefits ($11.2 bn), and Mexico one-tenfil (84.0 bn). Table 5-1. Macroeconomic effects of trade liberalization (immobile capital; no extemalities) USA Mexico Canada GDP 0.67 2.45 2.55 Material product 0.21 1.23 1.94 Capital return (real) 0.60 2.54 2.23 Wages real (net) 0.69 2.02 2.48 Labor supply 0.05 0.19 0.26 Private consumption 1.03 2.50 2.78 Exports 4.68 11.78 14.81 Imports 3.60 13.41 15.08 Terms of trade -0.84 -2.66 -7.38 The change in private consumption is generally higher finan finat of GDP. The difl‘erence is explained mostly by fine assumption of budget neutrality, which acts as leverage of GDP efi‘ects. For instance, if government consumption is 20 "/o and GDP increases by 1%, finer fine consumption efi'ect would be expected to be of the order of 1.25 °/..‘° Clearly, the leverage is smallest in Mexico due to a small government sector. Reduced government trarnsfers resulting from tarifi‘ losses also have an influence. The increase in real consumption is accomparnied by higher factor rewards. As fine relative increase in the economic pie is highest in Canada and Mexico, fine largest relative 3’Difi‘crencesinthechangesofexportsandinnportsareduetotherelativetr'adeandcapital positionofthecountriesinthebaseyearwiththeU.S.runningabalanceofpaymentdeficitand Mexico and Canada having a surplus. To preserve a constant external balance, exports and importschangeasomewhatdifi‘erentrate. ”1.25 °/o=l%/(l-20%) 166 increases can be found here. While in fine U.S. arnd Canada benefits are relatively neutrally distributed between capital and labor, capital is fine main beneficiary of trade liberalization inn Mexico. This is consistent wifin fine Stolper-Samuelson fineorem, Mexico is a relatively capital- abnnrndant country since, as was noted in Chapter 4. A secondary effect of fine increased purchasirng power of wages is finat labor supply arnd hence employment increases slighfiy in all finree conmtries, between 0.05 and 0.26 "/o. Next to fire allocation effect of trade, finis provides additional economic gowfin as fine absolute resource endowment rises. The mecharnism also explains why wages increase less finan might be expected (e.g. in fine U.S. which is relatively labor-abundant). mm A value-based definition of output (such as GDP) is misleading for capturing environmental efi‘ects of trade liberalization, because only material flows are remd to pollution. Instead, one needs an indicator finat captures changes in fine material finroughput Therefore, finis paper makes fine important distinction between GDP and material product, where fine latter is calculated as goss output wifin constant output prices. The substantive difference between fine increase in fine value of production and physical production is explained by fine fact finat even wifinout actually producing much nnore (in physical nnnnits) inn each individual country, fine better allocation across countries allows a substantially lniglner consumption (in value terms). Several mechanisms can be identified to explain fine magnitude of fine difi‘erences between fine values: First, fine removal of trade barriers increases fine purchasirng power of consumers. It simply allows cornsumers to allocate bette fineir consumption bundles. This leads to a higher increase in fine value of consumption finan fine pure quantity of goods would suggest. Second, fine removal of trade barriers allows for 167 reallocation in fine production process. This increases fine eficiency in fine production process, even wifinout inncreasing fine material finroughput. These two factors simply reflect fine fineory of comparative advantage. A finird factor is first a part offine trade distortion consists in norn-tarifl‘ barriers. By assumptiorn, non-tanifi‘ barriers lead simply to a waste of resources. These resources are now available for consumption (net output), which increases welfare even if production (gross output) were to remain unchanged‘1 While increasing GDP, all finese mechanisms afi‘ect pollution only insofar as finey might induce sectoral changes. mm The sectoral changes undemeafin fine macro-economic aggregates are listed in Table 5-2. Despite an overall induced gowfin in all finree econonnies, fine 26 sectors are afl‘ected unevenly, wifin all states showing net winners and losers. The table reports material product, because of its importance for fine calculation of ennissions figures. Changes in production values are qualitatively very similar, because physical output follows relative price changes. However, in some irnstances, sectors will see fireir output decrease in material terms but increase in value terms. Several sectors deserve particular mentioning. The first columns of each country in Table 5-2 show finat agricultural production clearly moves away fiom Canada and Mexico to fine United States. By contrast, petroleum production in fine United States shrinks slighfiy, giving a boost to production in Mexico and Canada Anofiler important sector is transport equipment, ‘" While this assumption concerning non-tarifi barriers has some significance on the calculation of thewelfareefi‘ectoffiadehberalinfiontheimpactonsectoral sizeandcompositionofthe 168 where production increases substantially in fine United States and Canada. Alfinough each country has a few shrinking sectors, finere is a general increase in manufacturing at fine expense of services. This shifi results from fine fact finat fine removal of trade barriers practically only afl‘ects manufacturing sectors. In fine data set a number of services are not even traded at all. The associated efiiciency gain finerefore moves fine relative advantage towards manufactured products. In terms of fine pollution efl‘ect of NAFTA, finis may entail an upward bias, as services are relatively clean wifin fine important exception of transport The second set of columns in Table 5-2 shows how fine relative changes translate inn absolute shifts in production. The values are calculated by multiplying fine values of fine first column wifir fine output values of fine base case. A monetary indicator for channges in material finroughput may be a contradiction in terms. However, it presents fine order of magnitude annd importance of fine sectoral changes in constant prices. Clearly, for bofin fine United States and Canada, fine effect of NAFT A is dominated by fine transport equipment sectors. For finese countries, fine shrinking of services also play an important role. By contrast, fine agicultnn'al and fire petroleum sectors, fine two biggest in fine economy, dominate charnge in fine Mexican ecornomy. econonny is small, as the composition of resource waste is identical to consumption. Changes in the economy occur only insofar, as the increased real income afi‘ects the labor supply ofan econornny. 169 Table 5-2. Sectoral calculation of emissions impact of trade liberalization (immobile capital; no extemalities) USA Mexico Canada Out- Out- Emissi Outpu Out- Emissi Out- Out- Ennissi put put ons t (%) put ons put put orns (%1 (bn 3) (bn 5) (%) (bn 3) Agriculture 1.66 3.25 0.000 -3.27 -0.73 0.000 -2.38 -0.79 0.000 Mining 0.18 0.04 0.007 1.70 0.07 0.161 1.16 0.14 0.205 Petroleum -0.75 -1.42 -0.114 14.11 3.05 2.688 9.36 2.49 1.139 Food Processing 0.88 2.61 0.039 2.41 0.62 0.260 0.40 0.14 0.020 Beverages 0.80 0.39 0.000 3.01 0.12 0.003 0.84 0.05 0.001 Tobacco -0.60 -0. 19 0.000 1.47 0.01 0.000 -1.62 -0.03 0.000 Textiles 1.33 1.15 0.003 3.15 0.12 0.010 -0.06 0.00 0.000 Wearing Apparel 0.72 0.45 0.001 2.29 0.08 0.002 -0.06 0.00 0.000 Leather 3.34 0.29 0.001 -0.14 0.00 0.000 2.79 0.04 0.000 Paper 0.21 0.45 0.005 -0.82 -0.04 -0.012 -0.82 -0.28 -0.032 Chemicals 0.51 1.02 0.006 1.35 0.14 0.017 1.38 0.22 0.016 Rubber 0.52 0.64 0.001 0.12 0.00 0.000 6.40 0.45 0.005 Non-Metal Minerals 0.26 0.17 0.031 -0.57 -0.02 0127 0. 84 0.06 0.093 Iron and Steel 0.93 0.68 0.019 3.75 0.15 0.139 10.33 1.07 0.377 Non-Ferrous Metals 0.74 0.52 0.016 -0.42 -0.01 -0.011 6.33 0.53 0.255 Wood & Metals 0.52 1.39 0.015 2.15 0.14 0.022 1.93 0.64 0.058 Non-Electr. Mach. 0.61 0.96 0.001 0.77 0.02 0.001 1.54 0.23 0.002 Electrical Machines 0.21 0.62 0.000 2.58 0.13 0.001 2.49 0.41 0.002 Trarnsport Equip. 3.61 11.27 0.041 1.87 0.16 0.015 33.43 19.01 0.370 Ofiner Manufactures 0.37 0.34 0.000 5.16 0.12 0.001 0.42 0.03 0.000 Construction 0.01 0.06 0.001 -0.34 -0.06 -0.011 -2.10 -l.69 -0.162 Electricity 0.37 1.00 0.099 3.76 0.15 0.268 -0.39 -0.07 -0.039 Connmerce -0.19 -1.67 0.000 -1.24 -0.55 -0.004 -2.70 -2.82 -0.006 Transp. & Comm. 0.02 0.07 0.003 0.15 0.03 0.024 -0.78 -0.50 -0.141 Finance & Insurance -0.33 -3.69 -0.001 -1.55 -0.25 -0.001 -2.77 -1.69 -0.004 Ofiner Services -0. 16 -3.38 -0.001 -0.25 -0.08 0.000 -1.26 -1.82 -0.003 Note: Ennission figures are normalized such total emissions before trade liberalizatiorn in each country are 100. 170 mum Irnportanfiy, material finroughput also constitutes an intermediate step for fine calculation of changes in fine pollution levels. The final columns in Table 2 illuminate fine environmental aspect of NAFTA It is calculated by multiplying fine sectoral changes wifin fine pollutionn coeficielts discussed in Chapter 4. Since fire absolute level of pollutiorn is not direcfiy comparable between countries, numbers are calculated to set pre-NAFTA base ennissiorns of TSP to 100. Clearly, fine change in fine petroleum sector dominates fine picture. The productiorn shift away fiom fine U.S. towards its neighbors has in its wake a substantial shift in pollution Petroleum overwhelms all ofiner changes in Mexico, wifin some additional impact from mining, food processing and electricity. This can be seen even better in Figure 5-1 where fine size of fine circles reflects fine contribution of individual sectors to fine overall emission charnge. If petroleum had an emission factor of zero, NAFTA’s net result on pollutionn inn Mexico would actually be negative. This aspect will be discussed furfiner below. In Canada, important contributions to fine overall pollution efi'ect are made by expansions in fine nrnirning and transport equipment sectors. Expansions in food processing, non-metal manufacturing, and electricity production, and contractions in petroleum influence fine result for fine U.S. I71 Figure 5-1: Contribution of Individual Sectors to Overall Emission Changes (ignoring regulation effect) USA Change in output (56) Emission factor Mexico 20 2‘, 15 g 10 5 .5 A , ° C G. E I V ‘ A ' fi 1 G 1 o -10 _5 f 10 20 30 40 8 0 ~10 Emission factor Canada E ‘5 e '5 o .5 2 T . I 0 30 40 Emission factor Note: Size of bubble represents overall errnission change (Table 5-2). White bubbles represent decreases. Emission factor = index for TSP cnnissions per dollar of output value (Table 4-9). 172 The sectoral ennissions changes sum up to fine total pollution efl‘ect of fine trade liberalization scenario (Table 5-3). Pollution in Mexico increases significannfiy (by 3.4 °/o), while finat ofCanada rises by 2.2 % and first offile U.S. rises only by 0.2 °/o. Table 5-3 finntlne disaggregates fine total emission impact into three components. The scale efi‘ect is equivalent to fine change in GDP. Pollution would change by fine same amournt as GDP, if no ofiner changes took place at fine sanne time. This efi‘ect constitutes an important driver of fine overall pollution efl'ect Values for Canada and Mexico are evidenfiy higher than U.S. values. Table 5-3. Emissions impact of trade liberalization (immobile capital; no extemalities) USA Mexico Canada Emissions 0.17 ' 3.44 2.16 1. Scale effect 0.67 2.45 2.55 2. Allocation efi‘ect -0.46 -1.19 -0.59 3. Common efi‘ect -0.04 2.19 0.21 Clearly, however, material product increases less finan fine production value. This meanns that GDP per unit of material product increases.” This increased allocation emciotcy earn be calculated as fine difi‘erence between changes in GDP and physical product In all finree cases, finis second efi‘ect reduces fine impact of fine scale efi‘ect substantially. However, finere is no case where it overcompensates for fine scale effect, because material product gows eveywhere. The composition efi‘ect constitutes a residual value, and is calculated as fine change in pollution first is neifiner explained by the scale efi'ect or fine allocation eficiency effect This efl‘ect provides a differentiated view. The production structure inn fire U.S. moves sliglnfiy 42T‘hisissinnilarinresulttoadematerialiaationoftheeconorny,whichcouldoccurdnneto technicalprogress. - 173 towards less polluting sectors. In Mexico, fine compositiorn change is substantial. It contributes to an overall pollution increase of 2.2 °/o. The effect on Canada is also to increase pollutiorn, alfinough only by 0.2 %. However, as can be seen from Figure 5-1, fine correlation between tradeinduced sectoral specialization and emissions factors is far fiom systematic. The ETERNA model setup leaves finree possible factors to explain finis composition effect First, it could be the result of the relative factor abundance of the countries involved As mentioned above, Mexico needs to be considered as capital abundant This mearns first it tends to specialize in capital—intensive irndustries, of which fine dominant petroleum sector is certairnly a part Second, since trade barriers were highest for fine manufacturing sectors and low for services, a relative shift towards manufacturing could be expected at fine expense of se'vices. Third, difi'erences in fine regulatory standards among countries (and hence difl‘erences inn capital costs) might reirnforce a specialization of Mexico inn pollution-intensive (or more precisely high- abatement cost) goods. However, abatement costs alone are inconsequential for trade patterns due to fine calibration process. In fine pre-NAFI‘ A case, sectoral difl'erences in fine abatement costs are exactly balanced by difl‘erences inn fine productivity of capital. Otherwise, finere would have been a difi‘erence in fine net return of fine sectors, implying finat fine ecornomy could not have been in equilibrium. 5.1.2. Introducing the Extemality The simulations just presented calculate emissiorns wifin a simple add-on approacln, wifinout incorporating its associated extemalities. Table 5-7 presents main efi‘ects of including extemalities into fine model. Compared to fine case wifinout extemalities, four more reporting categories are introduced. First, file variable “healfin” denotes fine change in fine extennality. Second, it is now usefinl to distinguish welfare and private consumption, because fine two now 174 deviate. Welfare is a composite of private consumption and healfin Third, as additiornal information, fine share of fine extemality in driving fine overall welfare efi‘ect is reported This figure includes production and hedonic efi‘ects. Finally, nominal and efi‘ective labor supplies are disfinguished, because healfin has a direct impact on labor productivity. Table 5-4. Trade Liberalization when Extemalities are included: Welfare Change (immobile capital) USA Mexico Canada Total welfare 0.94 2.23 2.41 Private consumption 1.02 2.45 2.74 Healfin 0.00 -0.19 -0.06 Extemality (% welfare) -0.94 -7 . 73 -4.56 Efi‘ective labor supply 0.05 0.01 0.20 Nominal labor supply 0.05 0.21 0.27 Efi‘ective labor supply consists of fine nominal labor supply adjusted for fine healfin afiect Changes in healfin affect fine number of actual work hours only inn a simple multiplicative way. The increase in fine wage sum finat occurs, because people are less sick does not act as a wage increase to which people adjust their labor supply. This is because bofin sides of the labor supply curve (leisure and labor) are affected equally by improving or worsening healfin. The impact of including extemalities on fine economic structure itself is not vey substantial, and finereforc not reported. Neverfineless, fine figures denoting fine relative contribution of healfin to fine overall welfare change show finat fine impact is not altogefiner negligible. In fine case of constant pollution technologies, lower healfin reduces fine welfare gain of NAFTA for Mexico by nearly 8 %. Even for fine U.S. and Canada, healfin reduces fine total benefits of liberalized trade by 0.9 and 4.6 %, respectively. 175 5.1.3. Introducing the Regulation Effect A next, step introduces a numerical formulation of fine country transformation hypofinesis. Abatement efforts are no longer constant. Instead, it is assumed that an increase in private consumption by 1 % is accompanied by regulations finat decrease fine permissible emissions per unit of output by 0.75 %. Numbers reveal finat fine impact of introducirng fine regulation efl’ect on environmental regulatiorn on macro-economic aggregates are small (Table 5-8). The increased abatement enmenditure acts to reduce overall production by 0.02 % in fine case of fine United States, while fine reduction Canada’s output is 0.06 %, and Mexico’s production is unchanged. Alfinougln fine gowfin impact of fine regulation on fine U.S. and Mexico are eifiner small or non-existent, fine reasorns for contrast with Canada finis are difl’erent. In fine case of fine U.S., file explanatiorn is simply finat fine income gowfin induced by trade liberalization is smaller finarn Canada’s. Consequenfiy, fine induced change in environmental stringency is also small. Inn finis case, emissions per unit of output must be reduced by 0.74 %, while emission stringency in Mexico and Canada increases by 1.8 and 1.95 %, respectively. By contrast, fine reason for fine small economic impact in fine case of Mexico lies inn fine small level of pollution abatement in fine country on fine one hand, and fine larger benefits of pollution abatement on workers’ healfin on fine ofiner hand. Healfin improves by more finan 0.1 °/o compared to a case finat ignores fine income effect. This increases effective labor supply by finis amount, and finerefore counteracts fine resource loss implied by risirng abatement costs. 176 Table 5-5. Central case simulation with immobile capital USA Mexico Canada GDP 0.64 2.40 2.46 Materialproduct 0.18 1.18 1.84 Capital return (real) 0.65 2.50 2.36 Wages real (net) 0.63 2.05 2.31 Efi'ective labor supply 0.06 0.10 0.24 Nominal labor supply 0.04 0.19 0.24 Exports 4.68 11.73 14.75 Innports 3.60 13.37 15.00 Terms of trade -0.86 -2.63 -7.32 Total welfare 0.95 2.30 2.43 Private consumption 0.99 2.45 2.66 Healfin 0.02 -0.09 0.00 Extemality (°/o welfare) 3.58 -3.36 0.00 Emissions change -0.65 1.52 0.00 1. Scale efi'ect 0.64 2.40 2.46 2. Allocation efi’ect -0.46 -1.19 -0.61 3. Composition efi'ect -0.09 2.17 0.15 4. Regulation efi'ect -0.74 -1.80 -1.95 The introduction of fine regulation efi‘ect changes fine net pollution efl’ect of fine NAFTA scenario firndamentally. The U.S. registers now a noticable net reduction in pollution by 0.65 °/o. The emission efi‘ect for Canada disappears from an uncorrected value of over 2 °/o. Only Mexico continues to have a net increase in emissions. However, fine values drop by more finan halfto 1.5 °/o. An interesting aspect of fine increased abatement effort is also finat finere are sliglnt secondary cfi’ects on pollution. First, irnsofar as economic growfin may be reduced, so is fine scale efi’ect on pollution. Second, finere is a slight shift in fine composition efl’ect In finis case, it induces all finree countries to move slighfiy towards less polluting industries. The two welfare components are affected in opposing direction by fine regulation eflect Gains in healfin counteract fine decrease in consumption. Despite reduced private cornsumptiorn 177 in Carnada and fine U.S., overall welfare increases slighfiy. By contrast, Mexico realizes a healfin improvement while maintaining an unchanged consumption level. The interpretation of fine welfare results requires considerable caution because finey obviously depend crucially on fine extemality estimates finat are used These are notoriously subject to uncertainties. As fine parameters used in fine simulatiorns regard only a sinngle aspect of fine extemality (fine healfin effect of particulate air pollution), it is sure to underestimate fine benefits of environmental regulation. 5.2. Introducing Factor Mobility The model is now modified by making capital mobile across countries. The mechanisms at large are fine same as described in fine previous case. However, in finis case capital moves to fine place of highest nominal after-tax return across countries. This is not fire case for real retnun to capital, which factors in fine consumption deflator. In fine simulation at hand, capital moves fiom fine U.S. to Mexico, while Canada’s position remains practically uncharged Accordirngly, fine output of fine latter two countries rises more finan under fire scenario wifin immobile capital. By contrast, production in fine U.S. even contracts. Obviously, finis shift in productiorn has cornsequernces for fine pollution levels in fine NAFTA countries. 178 Table 5-6. Central case simulation with mobile capital Indicators USA Mexico Canada GDP 0.61 3.30 2.47 Material product 0.13 2.51 1.86 Capital return (real) 0.75 1.95 2.31 Wages real (net) 0.59 3.06 2.33 Efl’ective labor supply 0.06 0.13 0.24 Nominal labor supply 0.03 0.35 0.24 Exports 4.27 16.94 14.84 Imports 3.46 14.72 15.05 Tems of trade 2.11 -3.25 -5.92 Total welfare 0.95 2.21 2.42 Private cornsumption 0.99 2.48 2.66 Healfin 0.02 -0.22 0.00 Extemality (% welfare) 3.93 -8.71 -0.06 Emissions change -0.71 3.79 0.03 1. Scale efl'ect 0.61 3.30 2.47 2. Allocation efi’ect -0.48 -0.80 -0.61 3. Composition efi’ect -0.11 3.13 0.15 4. Regulation efl‘ect -0.73 -l.82 -1.95 At first glance, fine movement of capital appears to be conmterintuitive. In particular, it contrasts wifin fine previously established notion finat fine U.S. ecornorrny is relatively labor- abundant Therefore, one could have expected finat capital flows into fine relatively capital scarce country. However, due to a larger relative importance of NAFTA, capital returns inn Mexico and Canada rise substantially more finan returns in fine U.S. However, Carnada’s increase capital return is near exactly matched by a substantial worsenirng of its ternns of trade, 179 and hence, depreciation. Consequently, U.S. capital follows fine higlner return in Mexico. The difl’erences in economic gowfin among fine countries are finerefore amplified“ Compared to a scenario wifin immobile capital, fine real return of American capital rises (by 0.1 %), while that of Mexico drops (by 0.55 %). As secondary efi‘ects, file capital nnovement causes wages in Mexico to rise 1 % more and finose of fine U.S. to rise 0.04 % less finan inn fine case of immobile capital. Consequelt changes in labor supply reinforce fine shift toward productiorn in Mexico. The production efi’ect is a nearly full percentage poirnt higher than wifin immobile capital. While substantive in terms of production changes and trade, fine difference between fine scenarios wifin and wifinout capital mobility is insignificant for fine welfare efi'ect This is because fine income loss or gain finat results from fine relocation of capital is compensated by profits finat are transferred across borders.“ Capital mobility also affects fine trade impact of liberalization. Two irnportarnt difi'erences to the case without mobility are worth mentioning. First, in the U.S. trade rises less than inn the case of immobile capital, because capital flows act as a substitute for trade. Second, despite constant balance of payment requirement, exports and imports develop difi’erently. This is ‘3 Barriers to eapital movenents are not explicitly modeled. The equilibrium assumption of ETERNA (or most CGE model) automatically presumed that an autonomous rrnigration of capital has already equalized national rates of return before trade liberalization. “ Because in the ease at hand, capital flows out of the labor-intensive economy (U.S.) into the capital-intensive economy (Mexico), the result could even be a decreased overall welfare. This paradox result can occur, because capital transfer entails an extemality in the labor supply function. With identical labor supply elasticities in two econornnies, a dollar in a labor-intensive economy induces a higher increase in fine labor pool finan a dollar in fine capital-intensive economy. Inthc case, whereinaddition health extemalitiesexist, iteanbedenonstratedthatcapital mobility is actually welfare decreasing. 180 actually corresponds to fine outflow of capital. The U.S. trade balance turns (nnore) negative, because of profit transfers fiom abroad. Correspondingly, Mexico’s, balance of trade turns positive to finance finese profit transfers. It should be noted finat fine case of mobile capital only constitutes a long-term equilibrium. This does not mean finat the pafin to finis equilibrium would be straightforward In particular, one would have to expect a J-curve efi‘ect, if fine modeling predicts large capital transfers. If, for irnstarnce, fine U.S. runs a trade deficit and finances it via profit transfes from investment in Mexico or Canada, fine U.S. first would have to run a surplus to finance finese investments, or has to borrow from elsewhere. If return on capital is 10 "/o, for every dollar deficit in fine steady state, fine country first would have to nor a cumulative surplus of rouglnly 10 dollars to finance fine necessary investnnents. A dynamic model might finerefore arrive at substantially difi’erent results than fine static one presented here. The sectoral impact of fine liberalization scenario reveals a picture that is qualitatively similar to fine one for immobile capital (Table 5-7). Sectoral gowfin and contractions take place in more or less fine same sectors as in fine case for immobile capital (agicultnnre; petroleunn; non-metal manufacturing; ferrous metals; and transport equipment). The obvious rnodificatiorn to fine previous scenario is finat in general sectoral values for fine U.S. are smaller or nnore negative, while finose for Mexico are larger, wifin Canada practically unafl'ected. 181 Table 5-7. Sectoral calculation of emissions impact of trade liberalization (mobile capital; no extemalities) USA Mexico Canada Out- Out- Emissi Outpu Out- Ennissi Out- Out- Ennissi put put ons t(°/o) put ons put put ons (%) (bn 3) (bn 3) (%) (bn 3) Agriculture 1.41 2.76 0.000 -2.08 -047 0.000 -244 -0.81 0.000 Mining 0.04 0.01 0.001 4.71 0.18 0.444 1.14 0.14 0.200 Petroleum -0.89 -1.67 -0134 22.32 4.83 4.253 9.34 2.48 1.136 FoodProcessing 0.81 2.42 0.036 2.77 0.71 0.298 0.37 0.13 0.019 Beverages 0.81 0.40 0.000 3.20 0.13 0.003 0.85 0.05 0.001 Tobacco -0.76 -024 0.000 1.86 0.01 0.000 -1.63 -0.03 0.000 Textiles 1.30 1.12 0.003 3.79 0.15 0.012 .004 0.00 0.000 Wearing Apparel 0.79 0.50 0.001 2.97 0.10 0.003 .003 0.00 0.000 Leather 3.30 0.28 0.001 0.38 0.01 0.000 2.79 0.04 0.000 Paper 0.17 0.35 0.004 0.23 0.01 0.003 -0.81 -0.28 -o.031 Chemicals 0.41 0.83 0.005 2.80 0.28 0.036 1.39 0.22 0.016 Rubber 0.42 0.52 0.001 1.23 0.03 0.001 6.43 0.45 0.005 Non-Metal Mineral 0.22 0.14 0.026 -019 -0.01 -0042 0.84 0.06 0.093 IronandSteel 0.80 0.59 0.016 5.02 0.21 0.186 10.35 1.07 0.378 Non-Fern. Metals 0.65 0.45 0.014 1.04 0.02 0.028 6.35 0.54 0.256 Wood & Metals 0.47 1.26 0.014 2.85 0.19 0.029 1.94 0.65 0.059 Non-Elect. Mach. 0.50 0.79 0.001 2.31 0.06 0.003 1.52 0.23 0.002 Electrical Machines 0. 13 0.38 0.000 4.84 0.24 0.003 2.51 0.42 0.002 Transport Equip. 3.52 10.99 0.040 3.39 0.30 0.028 33.50 19.05 0.370 Other Manufacture 0.35 0.32 0.000 5.94 0.14 0.001 ' 0.44 0.04 0.000 Construction 0.01 0.04 0.000 -0.62 -0. 12 -0.020 -2.1 1 -1.69 -0. 162 Electricity 0.32 0.86 0.085 6.44 0.25 0.458 -0.40 -0.07 -0.040 Commerce -0.23 -l.98 -0.001 -0.40 -0.18 -0.001 -2.71 -2.83 -0006 Transp. & Comm. -0.04 -0. 15 -0.007 1. 13 0.20 0.177 -0. 80 -0.52 -0. 145 Finance & Insuranc -0.41 -4.56 -0.001 -0.96 -0. 16 -0.001 -2.78 -l .70 -0.004 Other Services -0. 17 -3.60 -0.001 0.32 0.10 0.001 -l.27 -1.84 -0.003 182 Since changes in fine pollution level are driven by changes in sectoral productiorn, it is not surprising finat pollution in fine U.S. should rise less finan in fine case of irnnnobile capital, while pollution in Mexico rises furfiner. However, in finis case fine order of magnitude of fine charnge in pollution levels has increased. Main factor is a much larger importance of fine compositiorn efi’ect (driven by relocation of fine petroleum industry). In Mexico, fine composition effect contributes over 3 percentage points of pollutiorn growth, out of nearly 3.8 % in total. While loosing some of its industrial base, in terms of pollutiorn, fire U.S. is fine winner, wifin a net reduction of 0.7 %. While in many aspects for fine simulations fine question of capital mobility is relatively unimportant, clearly for fine environmental assessment of fine trade liberalization, fine question of capital mobility is crucial. In finis case, NAFTA would not only lead to a relocation of pollutiorn, but could potentially entail a net increase in pollution despite a large regulation effect. This would be fine case in particular under the assumption finat production in Mexico is substantially nrnore polluting finan in fine U.S., However, it should be cautioned finat to a substantial degee fine changes discussed are due to a single sector, petroleum production. 5.3. Importance of the Oil Sector 5.3.1. Leaving out the Emission Effect The simplest way to analyze fine importance of fine petroleum sector is by setting the emission coefl'rcients of fine sector to zero, while keeping fine remaining scenario assumptions constant This limits fine scenario changes to fine pollution compositiorn efi’ect Table 5-8 compares fine composition effect of fine two central cases (for mobile and immobile captial) to one wifinout fine inclusion of fine petroleum sector. 183 Table 5-8. Influence of the petrol sector on the overall emissions impact Immobile Capital Mobile Capital USA Mexico Canada USA Mexico Canada Compos. Efi’ect incl. oil -0.09 2.17 0.15 -0.11 3.13 0.16 Compos. Efi‘ect wifinout oil 0.07 ~0.31 -0.84 0.07 -0.59 -0.83 Total emissions incl. oil -0.65 1.52 0.00 -0.66 3.90 0.21 Total emissions wifirout oil -0.49 -0. 93 -0.98 -0.49 0.17 -0.77 Clearly, fine omission of fine sector causes important sign reversals across fine board for fine composition efi‘ect. While fine composition efi‘ect for fine U.S. changes from slighfiy negative to slightly positive, changes for fine ofiner two countries are nnore massive. Wifinout petroleum, Mexico registers a composition effect first is reduced by arournd 2.5 % for immobile capital and even 3.7 % for internationally mobile capital. The composition efi'ect of Canada dropsroughly 1 %. InbofinMexico andCanada, overall ennissiornsnowdropasaresultoftrade liberalization There is little difl’erence between fine mobile and immobile capital scenario irn finis aspect It is also important to note finat wifinout fire petroleum sector, fine central scenario delivers pollution improvements everywhere, with fine exception of a negligible irncrease in Mexico, when capital is mobile. 5.3.2. Exclusion of Mexican Oil Sector from NAFTA As a second way to examine the implication of exempting fine Mexican oil sector fiom trade liberalization, fine model was run leaving all bilateral trade barriers between Mexico and fine ofiner two states constant. To some extent, finis reflects fine actual situatiorn finat was negotiated in fine NAFTA treaty, where a number of restrictions for investnnent in fine Mexican oil sector remain in order to protect PEMEX (cp. Huflnauer and Schott 1993, p. 33-36). Table 5-9 reports fine results under fine assumption of intematiornally immobile and mobile capital. 184 Table 5-9. Exclusion of Mexican petroleum sector from NAFTA Innmobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex. Can. USA Mex Can. GDP 0.59 1.94 2.46 0.62 1.11 2.57 Material product 0.17 0.85 1.84 0.19 -0.24 1.98 Capital return (real) 0.60 2.02 2.36 0.55 2.47 2.07 Wages real (net) 0.59 1.56 2.31 0.61 0.73 2.45 Efi’ective labor supply 0.06 0.11 0.24 0.06 0.08 0.26 Nominal labor supply 0.04 0.15 0.24 0.04 0.02 ' 0.26 Exports 4.34 12.18 14.74 4.56 7.84 15.14 Imports 3.32 13.53 14.99 3.39 12.40 15.11 Total welfare 0.90 1.66 2.43 0.89 1.72 2.44 Private consumption 0.94 1.75 2.67 0.94 1.72 2.69 Healfin 0.02 -0.04 0.00 0.02 0.07 -0.01 Extemality (% welfare) 3.76 -2.10 -0.04 3.58 3.34 -0.42 Ennissions -0.65 0.69 0.02 -0.61 -1.14 0.20 1. Scale efi'ect 0.59 1.94 2.46 0.62 1.16 2.57 2. Allocation efi’ect -0.42 -1.07 -0.51 -0.43 -1.35 -0.59 3. Composition efi'ect -0.12 1.15 0.17 -0.11 0.37 0.23 4. Regulation efi’ect -0.70 -1.29 -1.95 -0.70 -1.27 -1.97 Unsurprisingly, on a macroeconomic level fine benefits of trade liberalizatiorn for Mexico are now about one half-percentage point less finan in fine base case. There is also a rnoticeable reduction in fine trade benefits for fine U.S. The reduced welfare gains are borne sliglnfiy nnore by capital owners finan workers. Owing to fine capital intensity of fine sector, finis could be expected. As trade between Mexico and Canada is minimal, Canada remains unafl'ected by fine exclusion of the oil sector. The limited NAFTA changes fine overall pollution efi‘ect substantially less finan fine earlier sensitivity case finat exempts fine oil sector fiom fine calculation of fine pollution efi’ect None of fine signs of fine individual efi’ects changes, alfinough fine net impact on Mexico’s pollutiorn level 185 is only about one finird of fire central case. Important contributors are a lower scale efi’ect, which is dampened by a reduced income efi’ect, and a lower composition effect In fine case of immobile capital, .fire drop in fine composition efi’ect could have been expected to be more substantial in light of fine earlier discussion on fine sector’s innportarnce. However, despite restrictions on trade, fine oil sector in Mexico still expands by a substantial 6 % (compared to 14 °/o in fine base case). This is due to growtln in energy arnd oil-intensive sectors in Mexico and has obvious consequences for emissions. For mobile capital, fine effect of fine change in fine scenario is identical in directiorn, but substantially larger in magnitude. Mexico’s GDP gains drop to a finird of fine central case. Capital flows to Canada and fine United States irnstead, causing even fine oil sector to shrink slightly. The production shift is accompanied by a shift in fine pollution pattenn Mexican emissions drop by more finan 1 %, instead of increasing by nearly 4 %. The sharply reduced scale effect and a substantially reduced composition effect domirnate finis change. 5.4. Sensitivity to Calibration Parameters Chapter 4 described extensively finat fine construction of fine model parameters had to rely on numerous assumptions and educated guesswork. Therefore, it is important to urndetake a systematic sensitivity analysis to test fine robustness and to explore fine parameters first drive fine results. The scenario assumptions will be finose of fine central cases (wifin and wifinout international capital mobility) wifin individual assumptions varied one at a time. 5.4.1. Using a toxicity weighted emission factor In finis scenario, fine use of TSP as an indicator for pollution is replaced by toxicity weights, i.e. an aggregate of TSP, S02, N02, CO, VOC (Table 5-10). The macro-ecenornic 186 impact of introducing toxicity weiglnts is small (less finan 0.02 “/11 overall). This was to be expected fiom fine discussion in section 5.1.2, which revealed a relatively limited macro— ecornonnic impact of fine environmental component Since fine use of toxicity weights is simultaneously linked to an increase in fine estimate for extemalities it is evident finat fine trade benefits for countries finat increase fineir pollution level (Mexico) become slightly less, while fine trade benefits of pollution exporters (U.S.) become sliglnfiy higher. This is reflected in a higher share of healfin benefits in fine overall result The use of toxicity weights has also litfie noticeable impact on fine direction of pollution flows. However, it should be mentioned first TSP makes up a significant component of fine toxicity weiglnts used Table 5-10. Replacing TSP in base case (immobile capital) with toxicity weights: Macroeconomic impact Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex Can USA Mex Can Total welfare 0.96 2.26 2.43 0.96 2.12 2.42 Private consumptiorn 1.00 2.44 2.67 0.99 2.45 2.67 Healfin 0.03 -O.13 0.00 0.03 -0.33 0.00 Extemality (% welfare) 5.14 -5.14 0.28 5.21 -13.85 -0.35 Ennissiorns -0.67 1.60 -0.09 -0.67 4.03 0.1 1 1. Scale efi’ect 0.64 2.39 2.46 0.61 3.29 2.47 2. Allocation efi'ect -0.46 -1. 19 -0.61 -0.48 -0.80 -0.61 3. Compositiorn efl’ect -O.11 2.26 0.06 -0. 12 3.27 0.06 4. Income effect -0.74 -1.79 -1.95 -0.69 -1.70 -1.78 5.4.2. Various Pollution Indicators Table 5-11 analyzes whefiner fine robustrness between TSP as pollution indicator annd toxicity weights is equally solid for its composite pollutants. The compositiorn efiect of fine previous scenario wifin different pollutants largely supports fine hypofinesis finat fine connposition efi‘ect is robust. Most values for fine U.S. show a slight negative trend, while finose for Mexico 187 are strongly positive, while values for Canada are slighfiy positive. However, clearly carbon nnornoxides (CO) and small particles (PM10) do not fit fine picture. CO causes sign reversals for Canada and significanfiy lower values for Mexico. PM10 even reverses signs for all counntries. This is surprising in particular, because PM10 is an important cornstituent of TSP. One explanation for finis may lie in fine quality offire original data set, as we have hinted earlier at some sectoral anomalies in fine relationship between PM10 and TSP". A furfiner explanation lies in fine dependence of fine results on only a few crucial sectors. Most notably, finere is a major difi’erence in emission values for PM10 and TSP in fine petroleum sector. Table 5-11. Comparison of the Composition effect for various pollutants Immobile Capital Mobile Capital USA Mexico Canada USA Mexico Canada 802 -0.07 3.74 0.18 -0.07 5.55 0.20 N02 -0.22 3.77 0.46 -0.24 5.57 0.46 CO -0.18 0.40 -1.46 -0. 19 0.65 -1.47 VOC -0.08 3.05 0.68 -0.09 4.46 0.68 PM10 0.02 -0. 15 -0.54 0.01 -0.21 -0.53 TSP -0.09 2.17 0.15 -0.11 3.13 0.16 Toxicity -0.1 1 2.26 0.06 -0. 12 3 .27 0.06 5.4.3. Abatement Elasticity As central case assumption serves an abatement elasticity (fine percentage reductiorn in pollution caused by a one % decrease in abatement expenditures) of 0.6. Howeve, in Chapter 4 it was argued finat fine elasticity might be as low as 0.36. This would make increased abatement efi'orts more costly. For instance, a regulation effect of one % will increase abatement costs by 2.8 "/6 instead of 1.6 %. However, fire impact of finis change results in ornly ‘5 For sornne sectors, the reported value for PM10 was higher than for TSP, which is by definition not possible, because clearly small particles (PM10) are a subgroup of total suspended particles. 188 a small reduction of trade-induced growth, because the overall costs of abatement are less than 1.5 °/o ofGDP (Table 5-12). Table 5-12. Simulations with a low abatement elasticity Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex. Can. USA Mex Can Total welfare 0.92 2.31 2.36 0.92 2.22 2.36 Private consumption 0.97 2.45 2.59 0.96 2.49 2.59 Health 0.02 -0.09 0.00 0.02 -0.22 -0.00 Extemality (% welfare) 3.88 -3.40 0.10 4.23 -8.67 -0.00 Emissions change -0.69 1.54 -0.05 -0.75 3.79 0.00 1. Scale effect 0.61 2.41 2.42 0.58 3.30 2.43 2. Allocation efl‘ect -0.45 -l.19 -0.60 -0.48 -0. 80 -0.61 3. Composition efi‘ect -0.13 2.19 0.11 .015 3.13 0.12 4. Regulation efl'ect -0.72 -1.80 -l.90 -0.7l -l.83 -1.90 5.4.4. Abatement Function Another potential source of bias may be that only capital is used for emission abatement Alternatively, abatement efforts could reduce the value added of a sector. In other words, irn each sector pollution abatement uses labor and capital in proportion. This has evident impacts on the incidence of pollution control. While in the central case the burden of pollution control is mostly borne by labor, in the alternative formulation it is more even It will not be completely neutral, if abatement intensive industries are more capital-intensive. From the evidence provided in Chapter 4, we know that there is some, thougln not strong, correlation between the two. Results from the sensitivity run show that the impact of the assumption is so small that it can be safely neglected. 189 5.4.5. Labor Supply Elasticity Of far greater importance is the sensitivity of the results to variatiorns irn the labor supply elasticity. To this end two extreme cases are considered: first, a completely inelastic, second, an infinitely elastic labor supply. Z 1.. In fine case of an inelastic labor supply, the scale efi‘ect of NAFI' A is sliglnfiy reduced (Table 5-13). This affects most macroeconomic indicators by the same order of magnitude. However, finereisasmallshifiinfinestructureoffineeconomy. Sincelaborismorescarce compared to fine base case, wages increase everywhere slighfiy, while rents fall. This leads all finree econonnies to become more capital-intensive finan in fine central case. Since capital- intensive industries tend to be more pollution-intensive, finere is a small compositiorn efl‘ect towards pollution intensive production. However, a reduced scale efi'ect and a reduced regulation efi’ect lead fine overall result on emissions to cancel out. 190 Table 5-13. Central case with labor supply elasticity of zero Irrnmobile capital Mobile capital USA Mexico Can USA Mexico Can GDP 0.61 2.43 2.33 0.53 3.28 2.20 Material product 0.16 1.13 1.70 0.06 2.36 1.58 Capital return (real) 0.60 2.43 2.14 0.63 1.76 1.96 Wages real (net) 0.65 2.24 2.48 0.65 3.58 2.61 Efi'ective labor supply 0.02 -0.09 0.00 -0.07 -0.39 -0.21 Nomirnal labor supply 0.00 0.00 0.00 -0.09 -0. 18 -0.21 Exports 4.66 11.68 14.62 4.24 16.76 14.51 Imports ‘ 3.58 13.31 14.86 3.42 14.55 14.75 Total welfare 0.98 2.34 2.51 0.91 2.19 2.35 Private consumption 0.96 2.39 2.51 0.89 2.31 2.35 Healfin 0.02 -0.09 0.00 0. 02 -0.21 0.00 Extemality (% welfare) 3.41 -3.30 0.00 3.91 -8.75 0.01 Emissions -0.64 1.52 0.00 -0.68 3.77 0.00 1. Scale efi‘ect 0.61 2.35 2.33 0.53 3.15 2.20 2. Allocation efiee -0.45 -1.19 -0.61 -0.47 -0.79 062 3. Composition efi'ect -0.08 2.18 0.17 -0.08 3.13 0.18 4. Regulation efl‘ect -0.71 -l.75 -1.84 -0.66 -l.70 -1.73 IE I ‘i The ofiner extreme assumption is a perfectly elastic labor supply function, or, alternatively, fine fixing of wage levels. Such an assumption increases significanfiy fine net efl‘ect of NAFTA (three quarter of a % for fine U.S. and Mexico, and 2 % for Canada). The econonnies become more labor-intensive wifin a relative trend towards less pollution-intensive production. In addition to increasing fine regulation effect, this mitigates or even over- compensates fine gowtln of pollution finat is entailed by fine increased labor supply. No difl'erence is noticeable between fine cases of mobile and immobile capital. Apart fiom fineir obvious impacts on labor supply and, hence, absolute scale effect of NAFI‘ A, changes in fine supply elasticity of labor have no impact finat in any qualitative way changes fine outcome of fine model. 191 Table 5-14. Central case with infinite labor supply elasticity Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex. Can. USA Mex. Can GDP 1.40 3.07 4.48 1.30 4.28 4.84 Material product 0.92 1.79 3.84 0.79 3.30 4.31 Capital return (real) 1.75 3.37 5.59 1.81 3.17 5.35 Wages real (net) 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 Efi'ective labor supply 1.27 2.32 3.80 1.16 3.30 4.19 Nominal labor supply 1.25 2.40 3.80 1.13 3.52 4.20 Exports 5.19 12.30 16.66 4.55 17.52 17.64 Imports 7.12 15.19 18.87 3.92 15.57 17.56 Total welfare 1.28 2.50 2.97 1.26 2.43 2.99 Private consumption 1.98 3.21 5.05 1.89 3.50 5.30 Healfin 0.03 -0.08 0.00 0.03 -0.21 O -0.01 Extemality (°/o welfare) 3.62 -3.05 0.08 4.00 -7.78 -0.52 Emissions -0.89 1.50 -0.05 -0.97 3.70 0.30 1. Scale efi'ect 1.40 3.09 4.48 1.30 4.15 4.84 2. Allocation efi‘ect -0.48 -1.26 -0.62 -0.51 --0.81 -0.50 3. Composition efl’ect -0.34 2.11 -0. 12 -0.35 3.01 -0.05 4. Regulation effect -1.46 -2.34 -3.63 -1.39 -2.55 -3.80 5.4.6. Demand Elasticities resulting in own price demand elasticities of roughly 1.4 for all sectors. A sensitivity simulation In fine central scenario, a consumption elasticity of substitution of 1.5 is assumed, reduces fine substitution elasticity to 0.9. The results of fine scenario are presented in Table 5- 15. As should be expected, lower demand elasticity reduces fine overall efi‘ect, alfinougln one might be surprised finat fine impact of changing this parameter is so small. However, even wifin a zero elasticity of substitution for private consumption, a positive trade impact would result This is one fine one hand, because fine import (or Arnnirngton) elasticity allows improvements in fine allocation of production even if consumption is unchanged Furfinermore, fine model contains a substitution elasticity of government consumption (set to 1) which would remain In addition, fine resource waste of non-tarifl‘ barriers plays a strong role. The benefit of reducing these barriers will be present, independent of fine size of macroeconomic change. 192 Table 5-15. Simulations with reduced demand elasticity (0.9) Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex. Can. USA Mex Can GDP 0.59 2.39 2.37 0.56 3.33 2.67 Material product 0.10 0.93 1.56 0.03 2.19 1.82 Capital return 0.67 2.41 2.39 0.81 1.86 1.86 Wages real (net) 0.55 2.16 2.34 0.49 3.12 2.58 Eflecfive labor supply 0.05 0.14 0.25 0.04 0.16 0.28 Nominal labor supply 0.03 0.21 0.23 0.02 0.36 0.28 Exports 4.24 10.93 12.76 3.66 15.96 13.53 Imports 3.23 12.43 12.80 3.02 13.88 13.12 Total welfare 0.90 2.28 2.56 0.90 2.15 2.55 Private cornsumption 0.93 2.42 2.78 0.92 2.41 2.81 Health 0.02 -0.07 0.02 0.02 -0.20 0.00 Extemality (°/o welfare) 4.21 -2.67 1.08 4.53 ~8.20 0.05 Emissions -0.73 1.20 -0.54 -0.82 3.37 -O.22 1. Scale efl'ect 0.59 2.39 2.37 0.66 3.20 2.67 2. Allocation effect -0.49 -1.42 -0.79 -0.53 -l.01 -0.85 3. Composition efl‘ect -0.13 2.07 -0.03 -0. 16 2.98 0.06 4. Regulation efl'ect -0.69 -1.78 -2.04 -0.69 -1.77 -2.06 The most important and obvious impact of a reduced elasticity of substitution is finat most numbers are simply smaller finan in fine central scenario. In particular, fine clnarnge in trade volume is reduced However, at fine same time some structural difi‘erences occur. Material product is relatively reduced, leading to lower pollution increases. This increases efiecfiw labor supply despite relatively sinking wages. The economy becomes more labor-intensive, becausewagesareafi‘ectedmorefinanrents.Itcanbenotedalsofinatfineallocafionefiectis higher finan inn fine central case, leading even to a slighfiy lnigher overall welfare irn Canada Considering fine lower substitution elasticity finis is somewhat conunterintuitive. However, finis efl'ect is fine result of an improvement in fine terms of trade with fine rest of world by 1 %, as fine lower demand elasticity compared to fine central case leads to a relative appreciation of fine NAFTA currencies. 193 5.4.7. Elasticity of Scale The inclusion of scale elasticities into fine simulation also has a relatively small efl'ect on fine overall results. The results of setting scale elasticity to zero can be summarized in very simple terms. For all finree countries, fine macroeconomic impact of trade liberalization would be reduced by 10 to 15 %. There is also a slight, yet unsystematic impact on fine pollution efl‘ect of trade liberalization. Capital mobility makes scale elasticity more important for fine recipients of capital (Mexico), but does not alter fine results much compared to immobile capital. 5.4.8. Revenue Recycling A furfiner set of sensitivity runs replaced fine assumption finat changes in government budgets are balanced through government transfers wit fine assumption that budgets are balanced finrough changes in labor taxes. This mechanism reduces labor taxes, because fine loss in tarifl‘ revenues is more finan compensated by increased government revenues induced by overall economic gowfin. Therefore, labor supply and GDP increase. However, fine net amournts of taxes finat could be redistributed are small. Consequently, fine impact of a switch to reducirng labor taxes compared to lump sum transfer is very tiny. Even wages would be afl‘ectedby less finan 0.01 %. 5.5. Variations of the Regulation Equation 5.5.1. Various Regulation Elasticities Clearly; fine level of regulation elasticity is crucial in determining fine net pollution efl‘ect of trade liberalization. Figure 5-2 shows fine impact of increasing fine irncome elasticity on fine finree NAFTA countries for internationally immobile and mobile capital. The gaphs are normalized such finat fine trade impact with zero income elasticity is set to l. 194 In fine U.S. and Canada, fine simulations indicate finat fine GDP impact of an increase in regulatory stringency is negative. For instance, in fine U.S., a regulation elasticity of 2 would reduce fine GDP gain by 10 %. By contrast, welfare increases slighfiy due to reduced pollution extemalities. For immobile capital, fine cost of regulation and fine increase in labor productivity appear to balance out exacfiy in Mexico. By contrast, overall welfare in fine country increases substantially, due to fine hedonic component of improved healfin Capital rrnobility has little influence on finis pattern, except finat it widens slighfiy fine discrepancy between GDP and consumption. It should also be remarked upon first in a configuration wifin toxicity weights (implying higher extemality values), fine evaluation of various income elasticities of regulation changes. Now, for Mexico not just welfare, but also GDP rises wifin income elasticity, because fine country has high extemalities and low abatement costs. In fine ofiner two countries, GDP still drops, as stringency increases. However, in bofin cases fine welfare efi‘ect is nnore positive. Of course, ultimately, fine welfare effects are largely a finnction of fine starting assurnnptions. The exact values are also not relevant for fine discussion of finis paper, which does not focus on fine question of an Optimal regulation level but on fine consequences of Figure 5-3 shows fine pollution effects of increased regulation elasticity. In all cases fine curve for total emissions drops somewhat steeper finan finat for fine regulation effect. However, the additiornal impact by output and composition effects are negligible in practice. For each country, one can derive fine finreshold value above which NAFI‘ A will be pollution reducing. (Evidenfiy, finis will difi‘er by type of pollutant). For fine U.S., the value is very low at about 0.2; for Canada fine value is 195 Figure 5.2: The impact of various levels of regulation elasticity on GDP and welfare (Zero elasticity case set to l) a) USA (immobile capital) 1.“ 1.02 1 O.“ O... 0.84 0.02 0.. 00.5 1 1.3 2.8 b) Mexico (immobile capital) 1.1 1.0. 1.00 1.04 1.02 1 0.“ e) Canada (immobile capital) 1.02 1.01 1 O.” 0.08 0.01 0.0. 0.“ O.“ 0.83 +°°'l +W¢lhn i-o—ooP +Woltare l +60? +Wellare b) USA (mobile capital) 1.04 1.02 1 I.” 0... 0.“ 0.02 0.. 0.88 O 0.. 1 1.8 2 2.5 d) Mexico (mobile capital) 1.1 1.08 1.0. 1.04 1.02 1 0.08 00511.52” 1‘) Canada (mobile capital) 1.02 1.01 1 0.” 0.88 0.07 0.” 110.611.5225 196 Figure 5.3. The impact of regulation elasticity on total pollution, growth and composition effect (percentage changes from pre NAFTA base case) a) USA (immobile capital) b) USA (mobile capital) as 0.5 e o 4.6 +roun «0.3 +11“ .1 +6rowfin .1 +Growtln 4.. +Connpoa. 4“ +Colnpoa. 4 -2 4.6 4.6 0 0.5 1 1.0 2 2.3 o 0.5 1 1.3 1 u c) Mexico (immobile capital) (1) Mexico (mobile capital) 7 s +roun ‘ l-e-roun +Orowth ‘ +M +Compos. ; +Cornpoa. 1 o e) Canada (immobile capital) 1) Canada (mobile capital) 3 s z 2 ‘ +Total ' i-e—rou ° +Growtln o +m '1 +Compos. '1 +Compos. sun 00.011.022.‘ lob 00.011.0210 197 aronmd 0.75. Mexico, by contrast, would need values between 1.4 and 2.2. However, finere may be good reasons to believe finat fine elasticity in Mexico is higher finan in fine ofiner two courntries, due to external and internal pressures, and fine simple fact finat fine country appears under-regulated. 5.5.2. Policy Function Connected to Wages The paper of Rome and Schulze (1996) is based on fine assumption finat fine goverrunent balances the interests of labor against finose of fine environment To assess finis hypofinesis, sensitivity runs link fine regulation stringency to real hourly wages instead of private consumption. Table 5-16 shows fine pollution result when a regulatory elasticity of 0. 75 is applied The influence on ofiner macroeconomic variables is so small finat it is not worfin reporting on. Table 5-16. Regulation effect as function of wages Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex. Can. USA Mex Can. Emissions -0.37 1.80 0.25 -0.40 3.38 0.27 1. Scale efl‘ect 0.64 2.40 2.46 0.62 3.31 2.48 2. Allocation efl‘ect -0.47 -1.19 -0.60 -0.48 -0.79 -0.61 3. Composition efl‘ect -0.07 2.18 0.16 -0.09 3.13 0.16 4. Regulation effect -0.48 -1.53 -1.72 -0.46 -2.22 -l.73 A priori fine simulations will be difl'erent from fine central case only irnsofar as wages and private consumption difi‘er. As in all cases wage increases are somewhat less finan welfare increases, fine regulation effect under fine Bommer-Schulze assumption would be accordingly smaller. Notably, Canada new reports a pollution increase by 0.25 %. However, small as finey may be fine difference between fine assumptions applied in fine central case and fine one applied here overestimate fine true importance of fine hypofinesis. More important is actually fine assumption of keeping government consumption fixed The policy 198 finrnctiorn is based on fine development of private consumption If government consurnptiorn is fixed, for a given GDP increase private consumption must increase at a higher percentage rate finarn GDP. Wifin government consumption share at arournd one fourfin (finis excludes transfers), fine leverage efi‘ect for Canada and fine U.S. is about one finird For Mexico, finis is somewhat smaller. For finisreason, fine difference between fine Bommer-Schulze assumption and fine one applied here should not be exaggerated. The results would be very similar, if the same innplicit elasticities were used in bofin cases. 5.5.3. Quantitative Restrictions An alternative presentation of fine regulation problem could be in fine form of quantitative restrictions of emission by sector. The government would set fine permissible emission per unit ofoutput such finat each sector would achieve exactly fine same percentage reduction in total emissions independenfiy of whefiner it might be expanding or contracting as a result of fine regulation. Sectors finat increase fineir output would finerefore face relatively tougher constraints, while emission limits for contracting sectors are relaxed The efl‘ect of such a regulatory mechanism is reported in Table 5-17. Table 5-17. Definition of restriction target in quantities of each sector Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex. Can. USA Mex Can Emissions -0.73 -1.81 -1.93 -0.72 -1.85 -1.94 1. Scale effect 0.63 2.43 2.45 0.59 3.32 2.51 2. Allocation efl‘ect -0.46 -1.21 -0.70 -0.47 -0.80 -0.67 3. Composition efl‘ect N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A 4. Modified Regulation efi'ect -0.90 -2.99 -3.63 -0.84 -4.28 -3.73 The values shown here are quite difi‘erent from finose of fine central case, which is essentially fine result of a higher de facto regulatory stringency as well as a difl‘erent irnterpretation of fine results. Most importanfiy, fine scenario assures finat fine ennissions 199 reductions desired by a country ex ante will actually occur ex post. In ofiner words, fine emissions impact of trade liberalization has a guaranteed negative sign. This is fine result of two clnarnges compared to fine regulatory setup in fine central case. First, fine composition efl’ect must be zero. By definition, relative differences in gowfin across sectors are exacfiy cournteracted by changes in regulatory stringency. Second, fine implicit regulation impact is substantially stronger finan irn fine central scenario. In fine central case, fine regulation effect is fixed, making fine emissions effect a residual variable. In fine case of quantitative restrictions, fine emission efi‘ect is fixed, leaving fine regulation effect to be determined. Sirnce for finis inherenfiy difi'erent mecharnism fine same elasticity of 0.75 is applied, fine efl'ective stringency is higher finan in fine central case, which prohibits a direct comparison of fine efl‘ectiveness of fine different regulatory regimes.“ As a secondary effect of finis increased stringency, finere is a slight reduction in gowth, as could be expected fiom fine discussion in fine previous section. Therefore, a quantitative regulation setting is not very interesting and would not need fine arnalytical tool of an integated CGE model, because fine efi‘ect could simply be calculated externally. Nonefineless, such a scheme nnight conceivably be employed to mitigate fine impact of trade liberalization, as losers are treated more lenienfiy finan winners. However, finis would leave open a number of questions concerning fine implicit formulation of environmental policies. ‘6 Comparable stringencies would require fixing identical joint impacts of income on regulation nninus gowth. However, this would not solve the fundamental dilenma that the overall emissions efl‘ect is a foregone conclusion. 200 5.6. Unilateral Actions 5.6.1. Unilateral Changes in Abatement Intensity A potential dificulty in interpreting impact of regulation elasticities consists inn fine assumption that changes occur in all finree countries at fine same time. This assunnptiorn leaves two open ends. First, since fine regulation level for Mexico is substantially lower finarn irn fine United States or Canada, even an increase finat is relatively higher in Mexico finan in fine ofiner countries might still increase the absolute attractiveness of fine country for polluters. Second, simultaneous changes irn abatement efi’ort do not allow an analysis of a unilateral increue irn regulations. Simulations of a unilateral reduction irn unit emissions by one finird illumirnate finis aspect. This increase in the stringency is ex ante only. To fine extent finat fine scenarios might change private consumption, fine ex post figure might deviate fiom finis. There is no discernible difl‘erence between fine impact of a unilateral increase in regulation wifin an wifinout NAFTA For finis reason, only fine pre-NAFI‘ A set is reported Therefore, in practice, NAFTA does not limit fine possibility to set environmental standards in any of fine countries. The direct impact of fine increase in U.S. regulatory stringency is forGDP to sirnk by 2.3 °/o (Table 5-18). The incidence of fine regulation falls exclusively on wages (-4.76 %), because effective labor supply increases by 0.35 % do to a large improvement irn healfin By corntrast, capital actually benefits due to fine demand for abatement equipment and fine irncreased labor supply (+3.17 %). The U.S. economy becomes more labor-intensive. The pollution efl'ect of fine regulation is noticeably higher finan what would be expected by fine regulation effect only. Next to fine contracting GDP, fine composition effect plays a substantial role, as production moves away from abatement and pollution-intensive goods. 201 I‘ll. Most of finis reflects actual changes in consumption, only relatively little of fine composition efl‘ect is conmterbalanced by concomitant increases in pollution-intensity irn Mexico arnd Canada For finese two countries, fine effect of production relocation is much too small to compensate finem for fine loss finey sufl‘er as a result of fine changes in fine U.S. Due to a simultaneous increase in import prices for U.S. products and a contraction irn their largest export markets, Mexico and Canada suffer GDP losses of more than 0.3 %. Table 5-18. Unilateral reduction in unit emissions by one third in the United States Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex. Can USA Mex Can GDP -2.28 -0.29 -O.29 -2.20 -1.01 -0.83 Material product -2.22 -0.02 -0.08 -2. 10 -1.20 -0.80 Capital return (real) 3.17 -0.31 -0.28 2.93 0.22 1.17 Wages real (net) -4.76 -0.27 -0.27 -4.67 -1.13 -0.94 Effective labor supply 0.35 -0.05 -0.04 0.36 -0.09 -0.14 Nominal labor supply -0.71 -0.03 -0.02 -0.69 -0. 18 -0.16 Exports -0.50 0.3 1 -0.08 0.43 -4.54 -2.06 Imports -0.59 0.33 0.02 -0.30 -1.03 -0.62 Total welfare -1.06 -0.36 -0.35 -1.06 -0.24 -0.34 Private consumption -2.84 -0.35 -0.36 -2.83 -0.35 -0.46 Healfin 1.07 -0.03 -0.01 1.06 0.09 0.01 Extemality (°/o welfare) -174.94 6.67 6.14 -174.70 -32.59 -7.35 Emissions -36.80 0.48 0.42 -36.69 -l.59 -0.50 1. Scale efi'ect -2.28 -0.29 -0.29 -2.20 -l.01 -0.83 2. Allocation efi‘ect 0.06 0.27 0.21 0.09 0.01 0.03 3. Composition efi‘ect -4.42 0.23 0.23 -4.37 -0.65 -0.05 4. Regulation efi'ect 32.37 0.27 0.27 -32.37 0.26 0.34 The difl‘erence between simulations wifin internationally mobile and irnnnobile capital is surprisingly small for fine United States. The U.S. is actually better ofi‘ wifin mobile finarn wifin immobile capital, because it attract capital fi'om neighboring countries. This might be contrary to intuition, as one could expect finat fine increased abatement costs leads capital to flee fine country. However, since capital returns in fine U.S. actually increase due to a higher efi‘ective 202 labor supply and lower wages. (It can be demonstrated finat fine two efi'ects cancel out, when fine healfin efl‘ect of reduced emissions is forced to zero.) The net capital migration to fine U.S. because of fine regulation causes fine composition efi‘ect in all finree countries to turn negative. This is a crucial difl'erence. In fine case of immobile capital, trading partnners counteract fine composition efl‘ect in fine regulating country. In fine case of mobile capital, fine allocation efi‘ect is exported to fine trading partrners. For finis reason, fine welfare and income effect in Canada is substantially rrnore negative finan for immobile capital. However, Mexico benefits due to lower pollution levels. Table 5-19 shows fine effect of a unilateral regulatory increase in Mexico. Given fine appropriate adjustment for fine size of fine economy, fine efl‘ect of increased regulation inn Mexico islargelyfinesameasfinatofaunilateral actionbyfineUnited States. GDP dropsinallfinree courntries. However, in fine case of Mexico, low abatement costs and high externnalities actually lead to an increase irn overall welfare in fine country. Again, owners of capital become better off finan wifinout fine regulation. Due to its small size, fine influence Mexico has on fine other two countries is minor but slighfiy negative. The composition effect induced in all finree countries has fine expected sign, but is small. Capital mobility reinforces fine efi‘ects finat occur in fine case of immobile capital. In fine case at hand, fine favorable effect of regulation on capital return leadsto a noticeable inflow of capital to Mexico. Finally, Table 5-20 reports fine Canadiarn case, which is mutatis mutandis fine same as finat of fine United States. 203 Table 5-19. Unilateral reduction in unit emissions by one third in Mexico GDP Material product Capital return (real) Wages real (net) Effective labor supply Nominal labor supply Exports Imports Total welfare Private consumption Healfin Extemality (% welfare) Emissions 1. Scale effect 2. Allocation efl‘ect 3. Composition efl‘ect 4. Regulation efl‘ect Immobile capital Mobile cmital USA Mex. Can. USA Mex. Can -0.004 -0.l88 -0.002 -0.006 -0.135 -0.002 -0.001 -0.363 -0.001 -0.003 -0.288 0.000 -0.004 0.359 -0.001 0.002 0.328 -0.002 -0.004 -2.860 -0.001 -0.006 -2.809 -0.001 -0.001 1.539 0.000 -0.001 1.544 0.000 0.000 -0.383 0.000 o0.001 -0.374 0.000 0.010 -0.125 -0.002 -0.013 0.176 0.000 0.014 -0.214 -0.001 0.007 -0.131 0.000 -0.005 1.012 -0.002 -0.005 1.009 -0.002 -0.005 -0.238 -0.002 -0.005 -0.236 -0.002 0.000 1.930 0.000 0.000 1.925 0.000 5.822 165.272 8.759 2.053 165.466 7.907 0.006 -33.855 0.003 0.002 -33.769 0.003 -0.004 -0.188 -0.002 -0.006 -0.135 -0.002 0.004 -0.225 0.001 0.003 -0.153 0.001 0.002 -0.539 0.002 0.001 -0.483 0.002 0.004 -33.254 0.001 0.004 -33.254 0.002 Table 5—20. Unilateral reduction in unit emissions by one third in Canada GDP Material product Capital return (real) Wages real (net) Efl‘ective labor supply Nominal labor supply Exports Imports Total welfare Private consumption Healfin Extemality (°/o welfare) Emissions 1. Scale efl‘ect 2. Allocation effect 3. Composition efi‘ect 4. R5gulation efl'ect Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex Can. USA Mex Can. -0.04 -0.01 -1.76 -0.11 -0.13 -1.05 -0.01 0.00 -2.21 -0. 10 -0. 15 -l.28 -0.04 -0.01 3.99 0.15 0.03 2.11 -0.04 -0.01 -4.87 -0.12 -0.14 -4.04 -0.01 0.00 0.25 -0.02 -0.01 0.41 0.00 0.00 -0.76 -0.02 -0.02 -0.58 0.04 0.00 -0.81 -0.64 -0.58 1.83 0.13 0.00 -1.41 -0.08 -0.14 -0.58 -0.04 -0.01 -0.76 -0.05 -0.02 -0.76 -0.05 -0.01 -2.44 -0.07 -0.04 -2.32 0.00 0.00 1.02 0.00 0.01 1.00 6.57 13.38 -228.64 -6.20 -52.31 -224.72 0.06 0.04 -35.17 -0.06 -0.23 -34.36 -0.04 -0.01 -1.76 -0.11 -0.13 -l.05 0.03 0.01 -0.45 0.01 -0.02 -0.22 0.03 0.03 -1.78 -0.01 -0.11 -1.43 0.04 0.01 -32.51 0.05 0.03 -32.55 204 5.6.2. Sectorally Optimal Regulation A fnnrfiner interesting simulation run is to test what would happen, if countries introduced an optimal regulation finat equalizes fine marginal abatement costs across sectors. Table 521 shows fine result of such a regulatory change. The abatement values are calculated to meet fine same emissions level as in fine pre-NAFTA scenario for a constant production structure. The level of stringency iswnot adjusted to account for sectoral changes finat are introduced by fine improved regulation. For finis teaser, fine overall pollution efl‘ect difl‘es from 2610. Table 5-21. Optimal sectoral regulation level Immobile capital Mobile capital USA Mex. Can USA Mex Can GDP 0.59 0.26 0.52 0.68 0.51 0.59 Material product 0.63 0.25 0.69 0.62 0.58 0.62 Capital return (real) -0.54 0.15 -0.72 -0.53 0.01 -0.59 Wages real (net) 1.05 0.47 1.15 1.04 0.72 1.08 Efl‘ective labor supply 0.09 0.07 0.16 0.09 0.08 0.15 Nominal labor supply 0.14 0.06 0.16 0.14 0.10 0.15 Exports 0.36 0.18 0.50 0.32 1.50 0.31 Imports 0.39 0.21 0.63 . 0.37 0.57 0.57 Total welfare 0.63 0.31 0. 75 0.63 0.30 0.75 Private consumption 0.80 0.33 0.87 0.81 0.34 0.85 Healfin -0.05 0.00 0.00 -0.05 -0.03 0.00 Extemality (°/o welfare) -14.34 0.84 -0.34 -14.26 -7.50 0.22 Errnissiorns 1.73 -0.05 0.05 1.73 0.44 -0.03 1. Scale efi'ect 0.59 0.26 0.52 0.68 0.51 0.59 2. Allocation efi‘ect 0.03 -0.01 0.17 -0.06 0.07 0.03 3. Composition efl'ect 1.71 -0.06 0.01 1.71 0.12 -0.02 4. Rggplation efl‘ect -0.60 -0.25 -0.65 -0.60 -0.26 -0.64 Since sectoral difi‘erences in fine marginal abatement costs are quite large, induced gowth is substantial and reaches 0.6 to 0.7 °/o of GDP in fine U.S. The gain for Mexico is only 205 0.26 to 0.5 % due to a smaller level of abatement expenditures. The improved regulation also induces significant composition changes, which, in fine United States, irncreases pollution compared to fine base case. This could mean finat fine more polluting sectors are relatively over- regulated, and benefit fiom fine lower burden finat is now imposed on finem. An alterrnative explanation could lie in fine incidence of fine regulatory change. It can clearly be seen that fine capital rents drops because of reduced demand for abatement capital. (The only country where capital does not suffer is Mexico, where benefits from trade wifin fine United States are more important finan reduced capital demand). By contrast, labor benefits fi'orn fine better regulation finrough higher wages. Consequenfiy, fine NAFTA econonnies move into fine direction of increased capital intensity, which influences fine sectoral emissions efl‘ect. 5.6.3. Some Considerations on the Optimal Emissions Level In finis context, one could also calculate an optimum optimorum, for which not just fine relative level of regulation would have to be fixed, but also fine absolute emissions. While an analytical solution is rafiner complex, finis could be done in a simple search procedure by increasing fine stringency levels until fine maximum welfare level is attained. However, in light of fine great uncertainties attached to fine values of extemalities, such a calculation itself does not provide useful insights. Instead, we limit ourselves here to some fineoretical consideratiorns. For fine functional form chosen for fine overall utility level", it can be demonstrated that fine optimal share of abatement expenditures in fine total economy is constant. This is shown in "Utility(U)isacompositeofmaterialwell-beingMandhealth(inaccordingtothecquation U=W. 206 fine Appendix This optimal share of abatement expenditure rises when fine extemality is high and abatement costs are low. The utility function implies a unitary elasticity of pollution abatement expenditures wifin respect to income increases. This mearns finat fine optimal regulatory elasticity of income would be zero. The reason is finat fine for fine selected fnmctiornal form, bofin marginal costs and benefits increase in proportion to income, leaving fine benefit- cost ratio of unit emissions unchanged However, for several reasons, fine functional form should not let one presume that fine income elasticity of regulation is zero. First and importanfiy, fine functional form is arbitrarily chosen for illustrative purposes. It could be changed into a linear expenditure function wifin minimum consumption levels to change fine income elasticity of healfin such finat a cetairn income elasticity of regulation is implied. Preference is given to fine present fnrrnctiornal form, because it is simple and has no influence on actual behavior. Furfinermore, precise information is unavailable on which to base a difi‘erent fimctional form. Second, fine furnction shows fine importance of good regulation. A move towards a better type of regulation (e. g fine sectoral adjustment simulated furfiner up) leads bofin to a lower pollution level and an increase irn overall abatement expenditures. Third, fine zero elasticity result only holds for an optimum pafin of regulation. It is highly doubtful finat any country has achieved finis. To fine extent finat regulation levels are below fine optimum, one would expect a higher increase irn regulation. Fourfin, fine functional form assumes irnplicifiy finat no structural change occurs irn fine economy, which would alter fine benefit cost relationship of abatement However, fine main efiect of trade liberalization lies exacfiy in a change in fine economy. Fifth, fine formulation reflects preferences and not a political furnction, which rrnight be different Sixth, teclnrnical progess in abatement wchnology is not irncluded in fine calculus of fine equatiorn, which would lead to a higlner level of 207 abatement and lower emissions. Wifin finese limitations in rrnind, a tentative resume of fine simulation results is drawn in fine next section. 5.7. Tentative Conclusions This chapter presented model simulations of trade liberalization under a large variety of difl'erent assumptions. Before coming to an overall assessment on fine finree empirical hypofineses on trade and environment, a brief synopsis is presented here. Conclusions can be drawmfirstenfineusefifinessoffineanalyticaltool itself; secondonfine concretecaseoffine environmental impact of NAFTA; finird, on fine importance of various factors for determining fine overall results; arnd fourth, on recommendations for environmental policy in an open economy. These four will be briefly addressed here. LEW The simulations have demonstrated that fine issue of trade and environment can be successfully addressed in a in a CGE model. Important limitations to finis approach can be found less in fine modeling itself finan in fine lack of reliable data However, fine possibility of data construction in fine CGE approach makes fine data problem much less constraining finan in alternative mefinods. A particular advantage of fine modeling approach chosen is finat it allows a decompositiorn of the underlying processes finat determine fine overall environmental result. The disaggegation into an effect on gowfin, allocation efficiency, composition, and regulatory stringency is also of geat assistance in identifying important data and policy parameters. 208 ' n i f NAFTA The simulations allow robust findings for fine analysis of trade liberalizatiorn. Of particular importance in finis context is fine model-endogenous regulation-setting. The model runs indicate finat concerns that trade liberalization might lead to an environmental erosion are largely misplaced for two reasons. First, fine correlation between trade liberalization and specialization in polluting industry is weak. The paper finds finat, as a result of NAFTA, Mexico specializes relatively in polluting sectors, fine United States in less polluting ones, wifin mixed results for Canada However, finis specialization is far fiom systematic and is dominated by fine trade impact on fine location of just one sector (oil and petrochemical industry). For finis trade specializatiorn, fine importance of difi‘erences in environmental stringency among countries is small. Instead fine trade specialization is strongly dominated by differences in fine relative capital-labor endownnents of fine courntries. The findings mean in practice, finat trade and environmental policies can be pursued relatively independent fiom each ofiner. Second, it is demonstrated finat even in the country finat ends up specializing irn fine relatively polluting sectors (in this case Mexico), trade liberalization results in at nrost a small deterioration of fine environment, if reasonable assumptions are employed for an income— induced demand for abatement effort. In many cases, it would finerefore be counteproductive to erect trade barriers, if one wanted to preserve fine environment at home and abroad. W The analysis allows to identify fine factors finat are important in driving fine results. Table 5-22 summarizes fine findings of fine various sensitivity runs. In terms of fineir importance, issues concerrning model structure and data can be sorted into a group of important factors and 209 a goup wifin low or predictable effects. To fine goup of important factors belong capital rrnobility, fine importance of fine oil sector, fine choice of pollutant, and, evidenfiy, fine regulatiorn elasticity. The impact of fine first finree factors on overall pollution is mainly finrougln fineir influence on fine composition effect, while regulations obviously reduce emissions direcfiy. Ofiner factors, such as fine value of fine extemality, fine abatement elasticity or functional form, labor supply elasticity, and econonnies of scale, have a small impact on fine modeling results. Demand elasticities can have a substantive impact on fine overall magnitude of fine trade impact, but leave fine structure of fine emissions impact unaffected. 4 li r The analysis of policy variables allows three important conclusions. First, fine regulatiorn elasticity is of essential importance for fine determination of net results. In fine central case, fine inclusion of finis parameter results in a fimnly positive environmental impact in fine U.S. instead of trade leading to a deterioration of fine environment. Despite substantive gowth, fine polhrtion impact on Canada is zero. In Mexico, fine trade impact remains negative. However, it is substantially reduced If it were not for fine special case of fine petroleum sector, fine trade ageement would lead to an overall environmental improvement It can finerefore be said that it is not possible to assume a firm link between trade liberalization and environmental degadation. On fine contrary, insofar as wealfin is a precondition for regulation setting, trade opening is likely to be an essential ingredient for achieving a clean environment Furfinermore, fine impact of gowfin is more benign, fine higher fine regulation elasticity is. This means finat from an environmental point of view fine key leverage should be at supporting political institutions in poorer countries rather finan in blocking trade. 210 i Table 5-22. Analysis of different factors on their influence on modeling results Factors Explanation of Macroeconomic Environmental Remarks simulation ' impact 1. Extemality Inclusion of a Lowers effective Small (less gowth Definition afl'ects health extemality, labor supply, balanced by less welfare assessment reducing also slighfiy lower stringent effective labor regulation) 2. Capital Allows capital to be Capital flows to Relocates pollution Important for mobility mobile intra- MX, CN due to across countries oveall analysis NAFTA economic growth 3.1mportance Allirnpactofoil Canrevertsignfor Sectorisextrernely of oil sector sector on emission structural and important for calcnnlation is left overall efl‘ect overall analysis of out pollution efl'ect 4. Exclusion of Trade barriers for Reduction in Lesser impact of Mitigates overall petroleum petroleum trade NAFTA benefits; NAFTA, but no effects, but results sector from between Mexico large changes in oil sign reversals are qualitatively trade and other countries actor still occur robust libe'alimtion remain in place due to intermediate dennand expansion 5. Variation in Use of toxicity Same as above Same as above. Results are robnrst, extemality index increases however, largely extemality by 40% due to high weight of TSP. 6. Pollution Use of alternative Possibility of sign Fairly robust results indicators indicators such as reversal but net effect for TSP, PM10, 802, individual pollutant N02, CO, VOC, is driven by fairly and Toxicity few sectors 7. Abatement Lower elasticity Lower gowth as Practically Negligble impact, elasticity makes pollution result of reduced unchanged but afl'ects reduction more regulatory cost- expensive benefit calculus 8. Abatement Labor enters Alters incidence of Not systematic No inflnrernce on fnnnctiorn abatement function regulation on labor aggegate values, nexttocapital andcapital,and butafl’ectssectoral individual sectors. structure 9. Labor supply Variation of labor Higher labor supply Pollution increases, Can be neglected elasticity supply elasticity ‘ elasticity increases but scale efi‘ect is within realistic from 0 to infinite GDP gowth mitigated by stricter range of elasticity regulation 211 continued Table 22 (continued): Analysis of different factors on their influence on modeling results Factors Explanation of Macroeconomic Environmental Remarks simulation impact impae 10. Demand Reduction of Reduces trade Less total impact Marked influence elasticities demand elasticities benefits (less than across the board; no on magnitude of ’ proportional) sign reversals trade impact, but inconsequential for qualitative results 11. Economies Set scale elasticities Gains of trade Slighfiy reduced Practically no of scale to zero specialization are scale efl'ect influence diminished by a small amount 12.Revenue Recyclingof Reduced labortaxes Noneinpractice Canbeneglectedin recycling government induce a tiny scale case at hand revenues via labor effect taxes or transfers 13. Regulation Income elasticity of Higher elasticity The higher the Extremely elasticity regulation varies reduces gowth elasticity fine lower important in oveall between 0 and 2 slighfiy; could be overall pollution. pollution impact of even positive in trade h’beralintion case of MX 14. Policy Instead of total Deviation of wages Not systematic and Can be ignored function income, wages from income is not very srrnall connectedto determineregulato- sogeatastomake wages ry stringency a difference 15. Quantita- Emissions are Sets lnigher Redefines structural No noticeable tive restrict- restricted by sector, restrictions for trade ennission efl‘ect impact on aggegate ions instead of per unit winners; slightly reenlts; difficult of output more balanced interpretation of sectoral distribution pollution change of effects decomposition l6. Unilateral Increase in Reduced or Large reductions Countries can set action regulatory unchanged growth possible in home regulation stringency by just in home country country; pollution unilaterally even in one country and trading leakage rrnininnal an open economy partners 1?. Optimal Sets marginal Lower abatement Knock-on effects Regulamry sectoral abatement costs of costs; higher beyond emission elasticity might regulation allsectors equal growthandwelfare neutrality dnreto increaseasresnnltof gains; composition sectoral changes better regulation; of economy moves however, this is not towards less analyzed here polluting sectors. 212 Second, regulations can be set independenfiy of fine trade regime. The simulations have shown finat even when regulatory stringency is increased by 50 % nmilaterally, there will be only small increases or even decreases in pollution in fine trading partners. This does not change as a result of trade liberalization. It should be pointed out, however, finat fine model could only accournt for changes finat are made on top of existing regulations. It cannot disprove finat sensitive industries might have already nnigated to pollution havens. Third, good regulation setting can yield a double premium. Foremost, it frees resources finrougln a better allocation of abatement expenditures and results in economic gowfin and increased welfare. Second, it improves fine benefit-cost ratio of regulation of regulations, makirng stricter abatement more attractive. The most can be gained by fine most regulated ecornorrnies. The induced composition effect is ambivalent. It appears finat fine rrnost polluting are at fine same time fine relatively most over regulated industries. However, finis is subject to fine caveat of statistical limitations. It does not emerge fiom fine simulations finat trade influences in any (significant) way fine optimal structure of regulation, as fine structural trade impacts are relatively small and unsystematic. The final chapter will summarize fine main findings of finis paper and put finem into fine analytical context 213 CHAPTER 6 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 6.1. Research Question 6.1.1. Introduction Much of fine economic literature significanfiy nnisjudges fine net impact of trade on fine environment, because it takes sectoral emission factors as constant However, finis assumption conflicts wifin fine common observation finat wealfinier countries apply stricter errnission standards. The paper shows finat fine inclusion of an endogenous regulation-setting in fine analysis substantially alters fine environmental results of trade liberalization The endogenous treatment of regulation-setting in a CGE model applied on a NAFTA data set indicates finat irn various simulations, stricter standards eifiner reduce net pollution efi‘ects to a fraction of their uncorrected values or, in most cases, lead trade to reduce pollution levels. This outcome provides evidence to what can be formulated as institutional optimism in fine trade arnd environment debate: pollution reduction from trade-induced institutional change compensates for fine pollution increase caused by gowth and compositionchanges first result fiom trade. Institutional change is a necessary condition for trade to have fine efl'ect of beirng environmentally beneficial. Policies to improve fine environment in ofiner courntries should, therefore, focus on institution building rather finan on trade. The remainder of finis section briefly recapitulates fine literature on trade arnd environment and develops fine fineoretical base for the analysis. Section 2 describes fine CGE model constructed. Section 3 defines fine policy scenarios applied to fine model. Section 4 focuses on 214 fine nnacroecornonnic aspects of fine simulations, while Section 5 traces fine environmental consequences. Section 6 concludes. 6.1.2. Literature Review: Traditional Pessimism Chapter 1 shows finat fine question of whefiner trade liberalization is harmful to fine environment has generated a substantial body of empirical and fineoretical literature (cf. surveys by Dean 1992; Beghin et al 1995; Ulph 1994). The fineoretical and empirical literature has advanced in a number of ways. The discussion can be divided into two important empirical hypotheses: (1) fine traditional pessimism and (2) fine poverty attraction hypofinesis. These are complemented by (3) fine institutional optimism hypofinesis developed in finis paper. The traditional pessimism hypofinesis on trade and environment derived fi'om a straightforward extensiorn of fine Heckscher-Ohlin model of comparative advantage: Traditional gssimism hmthesis: difierences in environmental regulations are an important factor in industrial location (industrial flight hypothesis). Since companies can avoid regulations by locating abroad, flee trade erodes the independence of a country to set environmental policies and exerts a strong pressure towards lax regulation (pollution haven hypothesis). A broad consensus has emerged in fine literature finat regulatory difl'erences(wifin some exceptions) have, at best, a negligible impact on industrial location largely due to fineir small cost share. This result emerges bofin from studies looking at foreign direct investment (Leonard 1988; Xing arnd Kolstad 1996; Bouman 1996; Birdsall and Wheeler 1992) arnd trade flow 215 analysis (Walter 1973 ; Kalt 1988; Jafl‘e et al. 1995; Robison 1988; Sorsa 1994; Low and Yeats 1992; Tobey 1990; van Beers and van den Bergh 1996, Scherp and Suardi 1997).“ In its wake, fine empirical consensus has substantially reduced fine weight trade considerations have on regulation setting. There is also litfie evidence to suggest that countries (at least consciously) lure businesses wifin low environmental standards (Leonard 198 8). However, fine consensus finat regulation setting is not of geat importance in industrial location still leaves fine problem finat trade between countries wifin vastly difl‘erent regulations might have a quite damaging environmental impact This is particularly important irn fine context of North-South trade, where econorrnic specialization in polluting sectors can meet low environmental standards (Walter arnd Ugelow 1979; Copeland and Taylor 1994 1995; Chichilrnisky 1994). A modified empirical hypofinesis can be formulated. Rover-Lu mgg‘on Mthesis: pollution-intensive sectors tend to be attracted to poor countries. Free trade leads to environmental degradation in poor countries, because the trade specialization is met with lax environmental regulation. The poverty attraction hypofinesis differs from fine traditional pessimism hypofinesis irn two aspects. First, while fine traditional pessinnism hypofinesis applies also to countries wifin equal levels of development, fine poverty attraction hypofinesis expressly centers on courntries at differing levels of economic development Second, while regulatory difl‘erences drive fine traditional pessimism hypofinesis, finis factor is incidental for fine poverty attraction hypofinesis. Specialization results from ofiner factors such as relative capital endowments or difl‘erences irn “Howeve,theassenbledevidencenmybeweakenedbythefactthatmostnudiesrelyonthe 216 human capital. The evidence lends some support to environmentalist fears. A number of enpirical studies confirm finat developing countries tend to specialize in dirty industries (Hettige et al. 1992; Low and Yeats 1992; Birdsall and Wheeler 1992, Dessus arnd Bussolo 1998). 6.1.3. The Environmental Kuznets Curve Anofiner branch of empirical research hints finat fine relatiornship between a country’s wealfin and pollution follows an inverted U (Selder and Song 1994; World Bank 1992; Shafik 1994; Grossman and Krueger 1995; Lucas at al. 1992; Rock 1996)". This phenomenon is known also as environmental Kuznets curve. It denotes fine observation finat fine least developed countries have relatively low levels of toxic release, countries undergoing industrialization are highly polluted, and post-industrial countries are relatively clean. However, finese findirngs are contested. Neifiner is it clear where fine turning point nnight be located, nor does fine absolute level of pollution decline in all cases (Esty and Gentry 1998). Furfinennore, some resource degadation in early development phases might not be reversible. A part of fine observed environmental Kuznets curve can be explained by fine typical economic development pattern. Durirng an early development phase, a risirng pollutiorn level accompannies fine economic specialization in fine relatively dirty secondary sector. During a later development phase, a falling pollution level follows the gowfin of fine relatively clean tertiary sector. This development results from fine interaction of factor endowment wifin fine structure of same data set compiled by fine World Bank (Hettige et al. 1995) on which this study also draws. ‘9 Lopez (1994) derives the result fiom a theoretical model. 217 denand Poor countries tend to have a high demand for basic productiorn, which tends to be dirty, bofin for final consumption goods, as well as for investment Cornsurrnption irn wealthier countries tends to be more directed towards durable, semi-durable and perishable goods and services. At first glance, finis observation supports fine poverty attraction hypofinesis. However, finis hypothesis alone cannot explain fine reduction in pollution, because in practice dirty sectors shrinks only in relative but not in absolute terms. 6.1.4. Decomposition of Pollution The mecharnisms that could explain fine downward sloping part of fine envirorunental Kuznets curve can best be explained by disaggegating pollution causation into four components”, all of which are affected by fine trade regime (Figure 6-1). Figure 6-1. Decomposition of Pollution Causation Pollution = GDP ‘ Production * 2c, * Pollution , / GDP / Production, 1. Scale 2. Allocation Efficiency 3. Composition 4. Emission factor (Regulation) - 5° Grossman and Krueger (1995) and the World Bank (1992) use a similar decomposition of pollution causation. 218 1mm ceteris paribus pollution should increase in proportion to GDP. Beglnin arnd Potier (1997) show in a survey finat in many cases oftrade liberalization fine scale efi‘ect is substantially more important finan induced changes in fine ecornorrnic composition. W to fine extent finat GDP can be produced wifin fewer resources, fine scale efl'ect needs to be corrected downwards. Generally, finis allocation efi‘ect (denoting increased factor efficiency) is driven by factor neutral technological progess.’l However, irn additiorn, trade liberalization afi‘ects finis factor finrough (a) nrore eficient production pattens; (b) a welfare improving redistribution of output, even if production did not change at all (barter effect); and (c) fine reduction in non-tariff barriers means finat fewer resources are wasted in rent seeking, but increase are directed to net output. W: fine composition efi‘ect denomirnates fine change irn emissions finat would take place iftotal output and technology stayed fine same, arnd only sectoral slnares changed The composition efl‘ect of trade is at fine heart of classical arnd fine povety attraction hypofineses. 4 ' mi ion r ff :emissionsperunitofoutputareafl‘ectedbytnm factors. First, emissions could decrease as a result of non-neutral technological progess, which reduces fine productivity of fine environment as a sink for production wastes. Secornd, regulations reduce fine amount of permissible emissions and force industries to enploy pollution abatement technologies. The downward sloping Kuznets curve can only take place, if errnissions per nrrnit of output decrease during fine course of economic development The 219 necessity of a drop in ennissiorn factors points to a very important gap in fine literature on fine trade-environment link. It will be shown below finat fire omission of finis efi'ect substantially nnisjudges fine net effect of trade liberalization on pollution. 6.1.5. Institutional Optimism Hypothesis The unilateral focus of fine literature on fine demand side aspects of trade biases fine analytical results because it takes factor endowments and institutions as cornstant These assumptions result in an easy detenninacy of fine direction of trade-induced change: Trade is bad for environment, because it moves dirty industries to places where regulatory enforcement is weak (alfinough fine enforcement itself may not be fine driver). However, as Chapter 2 argued, finere is ample evidence that fine trade-induced wealth should lead to a reduced pollution intensity per writ of output across fine economy. Three causal chains can be identified finat nrnight contribute to institutional change. First, pollution control requires fine existence of furnctiorning regulatory irnstitutions. The existence of finese institutions is intimately tied to a country’s wealfin, because fine demand for environmental quality is highly income elastic.Clean environment is not simply a consumption amenity. It also reduces production costs due toreduced costs for clean-ups or its importance for healfin and, hence, productivity of fine workforce. In certain high tech sectors, a clean environment even ranks as a precondition for attracting high skilled labor. 5' The World Bank (1992) calls this factor neutral technical change increased input-output eficiency. 220 The difi‘erence in institutional capacity between poor and rich countries is often remarked (Chichilnisky,1994; O’Connor 1994). Dasgupta et al. (1995) find empirically that fine amount of regulation increases steadily wifin fine gowfin of per capita incomes. A clear link can be established between fine income and education level of fine country and fine level of public accountability of fine administration (Hettige et al. 1996).” Therefore, at a conceptual level, a number of aufinors have argued finat trade opening should be accompanied by institutional reform (Copeland 1996; Beghin et al. 1997; Runge 1994). Second, it can be argued finat trade itself, as opposed to autarky, increases fine stock of knowledge by giving a country access to foreign innovations and knowledge (Grossmarn and Helpman 1995). Trade openness itself might finerefore be associated wifin a cleaner industrial base (Birdsall and Wheeler 1992; Lucas at al. 1992). One component is finat multirnationals tend to apply similar standards to fineir operations globally (Pearson 1987; Warhurst and Isrnor 1996, Levy 1995). However, fine evidence on outward orientation and decreasing pollution- intensity has been questioned by Rock (1996). Third, changes in fine quality of factor endowments reinforce fine trend toward lower emission intensities. In poor countries, capital stock is likely to be of old vintage and nnore polluting finan newer equipment Retrofitting is generally expensive. Therefore, environmental improvements are linked to fine replacement of fine capital stock Low levels of capital endowment make environmental investrrnents expensive in foregone production Furtlnermore, a pool of unskilled labor gives a comparative advantage to traditional smokestack industries. ’2 Selden and Song (1994) provide similar arguments. 221 However, fine literature has largely ignored that environmental policy is endogenous to wealfin creation. One exception is Bommer and Schulze (1996) who link regulation to labor income. A higher level of wealfin can create fine regulations finat reduce fine pollution resulting from fine industrial expansion finat accompanies trade. The importance of fine trade-induced greening of production can be formulated as an alternative empirical hypofinesis on trade and environment: Institutional optimism hmthesis: trade-induced wealth creates demand jbr stricter environmental regulations. This wealth eflect on regulations can annul the pollution- increasing ejects of trade-induced economic expansion and specialization in pollution- intensive sectors. Alfinough fine arguments for fine institutional optimism hypofinesis are not new, so far it has not been explicitly formulated or subjected to an empirical test This paper fills fine gap by applying a CGE model finattreats regulation setting as an endogenous function of wealfin The model allows testing the institutional optimismhypothesis by comparing the pollution. increasing effects of econonnic growfin and trade specialization wifin fine pollution-reducing effect of wealfin creation. The hypofinesis is applied to various trade policy scenarios among NAFI‘ A participants, which serves as a nnicrocosm of North-Soufin trade relationships. It is shown finat fine perceived conflict between trade and environmental interests is largely fine result of a misunderstanding in fine full impact of trade openness. In many cases, fine regulation efl'ect is strong enough for trade liberalization to result in globally reduced pollution levels. 6.2. Model Description and Calibration Thanks to fineir versatility, CGE models have been fiequenfiy used in fine context of trade and environment interactions. These aspects are discussed in Chapter 3. However, no model 222 has incorporated all of fine finree aspects finat set pollution apart from ofiner production factors. First, pollution depends not just on sectoral output, but on policies. This fact requires fine inclusion of an abatement function in fine model, as, for irnstance, in Dessus and Bussolo (1998) or Beghin et al. (1995), wifin an application to Mexico. Second, fine economic evaluation requires fine imputation of environmental extemalities (e. g. provided by Ballard and Medema 1995; Copeland and Taylor 1995; and Srrnifin and Espinoza 1996). Third, fine assumption of constant regulations, and hence constant emission factors, needs to be relaxed (of. Home arnd Schulze 1996). 6.2.1. Social Accounting Matrix The model used in finis paper is comparative-static and calibrated on fine data contained irn fine Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) of Reinert et al. (1993). The SAM includes 26 sectors inn fine finree NAFTA countries (USA, Canada, and Mexico) and is based on 1988 data. This mearns finat any trade liberalization effects will also include fine impact of fine Canadian American Free Trade Agreement (CAFT A). The SAM does not include any information on environmental aspects of production. Notably, capital used in each sector needs to be split intocapital used for abatement and directly productive purposes. 6.2.2. Production Producers areassumed to be profit maximizers. Production follows a nested constant elasticity of substitution (CBS) structure. The top nest combines value added and intermediate goods. The model allows for econonnies of scale at finis level. The intermediate aggregate is obtained by combining products in fixed proportion. Value added is decomposed into a labor and a capital component. Capital can be moved between sectors and employed for production itself and pollution abatement It belongs to bofin domestic and foreign owners. The overall 223 stock of capital in fine economy is fixed. In fine model, an increase in wealfin is filerefore not accompanied by a higher capital stock. 6.2.3. Households Private demand is obtained by maximizing fine nested utility fnmction of a representative household. In fine top nest, fine household chooses between leisure and consumption. This function also determines labor supply. Labor supply is expressed in eficiency urnits,i.e. value added, not in hours worked. In addition to wages, households get revenues fiom government transfers and profits. Consumption e demand for individual products is file result of a CBS function finat combines fine product of fine individual sectors. Because fine CBS dernnand function has unitary income elasticities, fine model does not capturewealfil-induced changes irn fine structure of demand. Smifin and Espinoza (1996) have analyzed filis aspect, but fineir results suggest that finese demand effects are relatively unimportant. 6.2.4. Government The model includes a number of taxes, such as VAT, sales taxes, income taxes, capital taxes and customs duties. These revenues are used for transfers to households and fine provision of public goods. The public good is a CBS composite of various types of government consumption goods. 6.2.5. Trade The model follows fine standard Armington (1969) procedure of combining foreign and domestic goods to an aggregate, which can finen be used for private or government consumption or. as intermediate input. In parallel to imports, export supply is modeled as a 224 cornstant elasticity of transformation function. The assurrnption that fine balance of paymentalways remains fine same as in fine base year yields model closure. Tarifi‘ rates are calculated from fine SAM and are defined as actual collectiorn rates. Additionally to tariffs, non-tariff barriers are included Values are taken from Roland-Holst et al. (1993). It is assumed here finat fine value of fine non-tarifi barriers does not accrue to any economic actor as rent, but constitutes waste of economic resources used for rent-seeking. In fine case of trade liberalization, file reduction in non-tarifi' barriers leads to an increase in resources for import consumption. 6.2.6. Emissions and Abatement Physically, pollution is a joint output of production. However, in fine production function, emissiorns are treated as input in addition to labor and capital, because higher permissible emissions reduce sectoral production costs. This is fine standard approach of fine trade and environment literature. For manufacturing, fine sectoral emission factors per productiorn nmit of fine model are derived from fine International Pollution Projection System (IPPS) database (Hettige et al. 1995).’3 As is elaborated in Chapter 4, emission factorsfor non-manufacturing sectors are added fiom ofiner sources (Jansen 1998). This paper concentrates on airenissions. Data are available for sulfur dioxide (802), nitrogen dioxide (N02), volatile organic compounds (VOC), carbon monoxide (CO), and total suspended particles (TSP). However, fine ’3 The application of these intensities across countries is mm with numerous problens. There are even large variations wifinin countries (Paljal and Wheeler 1995). 225 analysis focuses on TSP, since it is fine nnost consistent pollution indicator for human healtln. Pollution from fine process of consumption is omitted in fine analysis, except for road transport Sectoral abatement data expenditures for fine United States are derived fiom fine Low (1992). This relationship is extrapolated to fine ofiner two countries. The assumption is that unit abatement costs and emissions in Canada are identical wifin finose of fine U.S. Mexico’s abatement costs are assumed to be substantially lower (one sixfin of fine U.S. for all sectors), based on simple data inspection of U.S. and Mexican emissions irnventories. However, sectoral ennissions and abatement factors can vary as a result of changes in regulatory stringency. Unit ennissions factors depend on unit abatement expenditures finrougln a simple constant-elasticity function. For each sector, an increase in baseline abatenent expenditures by 1%, decreases unit emissions by 0.6%. The emissions functions allow a representation of four important efi‘ects of trade on pollution First, an increase in production is linked to an increase in emissions (scale efl'ect). Second, ennissiorns factors are based on production volume, not production value. The pollutiorn factors per dollar of net output will drop (allocation efi‘ect), because, fine simple barter efi‘ect of trade improves welfare wifinout even when production does not change and, furthermore, less resources are spent on rent-seeking. Third, structural changes inn fine economy translate into emission changes (composition effect). Finally, finrough changes in fine level of abatement, it is possible to reduce emissions per unit of output (regulation efi‘ect). 6.2.7. Extemality Environmental extemalities are modeled in a very simplified way. Only fine healfin efi‘ect of air pollution, or more precisely small particles, which are calculated from TSP emissions, is incorporated Values for healfin efi‘ects are taken from fine econometric data of Ostro (1987), 226 which links air quality data to fine number of sick days. This formula was applied to air quality data of fine OBCD(1995) and Ronnieu et al. (1990). The approach translates emission changes into changes in labor output. In additiorn, fine welfare function assumes a hedonic value of pollution of twice fine lost output value to take account of suffering, sick days of non-workers, and early mortality. However, fine exterrnality figures are likely to underestimate fine overall impact of pollutiorn, as damages to cr0ps arnd capital equipment and fine impact of ofiner associated pollutants are omitted Sensitivity runs were used to analyze fine impact of a toxicity-weighted aggregate of pollutants finat increases fine extemality of particulates by roughly 40%. 6.2.8. Institutions The permissible pollution and, consequently, fine necessary pollution-abatement expenditures per unit of production are model-endogenous. The model solution algorifinm determines finem simultaneously wifin all ofiner economic variables. Functionally, regulatory stringency is linked to changes in real disposable income and follows a constant elasticity fnmction. Unfortunately, finere is no literature finat would support any particular value. The central case assumes finat an increase in private consumption by 1% leads to 0.75% tighter emission standards per nunit of output The choice for a central value is based sirrnply on plausibility considerations. If fine value were one or larger, it would mean finat, in practice, pollution would be unlikely to ever become a problem in any country over its wlnole development pafin. This conclusion cannot be squared wifin fine empirical observatiorn of fine inverted U-shaped pollution curve. By contrast, fine model does not include any ofiner emission reducing teclnrnology changes finat might happen However, in a comparative static model formulation, such a modemization 227 efi‘ect takes fine same form as regulation-induced abatement The elasticity values could finerefore even be interpretedto incorporate bofin factors. 6.3. Policy Scenarios and Baseline 6.3.1. Policy Scenarios The analysis of fine trade and environment complex finat is discussed at lengfin irn Chapter 5 centers on four main policy scenarios around which also a number of sensitivity runs were undertaken. The abolition of all NAFTA trade barriers asng no transborder capital rrnobility. In fine model, intra-N'AFTA tarifi'rates are set to zero. All ofiner tax rates as well as fine oveoll provision of fine public good remain constant. Changes in government revenues in fine policy scenario translate into changes in transfers. The reduction in non-tarifi' barriers is assumed to make formerly urnproductive resource (used for rent-seeking) available as increased net output. The trade closure of finis scenario assumes finat exchange rates adjust to keep fine balance of trade of each country at its pre- NAFTAlevel (measured in international currency). Capital carnrnot be transferred across countries. Serenade; The abolition of all NAFTA trade barriers assuming intra-NAFT A capital mobility. This scenario resembles fine previous, except finat it permits capital mobility wifinin fine NAFTA area. This mobility means finat instead of leaving fine balance of trade constant, fine balance of payment (including capital transfers) remains at pre-NAFT A levels. 228 Sammie}; Trade liberalization wifin restrictions in fine petroleum sector wifin and wifinout assumed capital nnobility (Scenarios 3a and 3b). Simulations leave all bilateral trade barriers between Mexico and fine ofiner two states for fine petroleum sector intact, to examine its overriding importance for fine Mexican economy as well as its high pollution intensity. To some extent, finis scenario reflects fineactual NAFTA treaty, whereanumber ofrestrictiorns forinvestmerntin fine Mexicarn oil sector remain (cp. Hufbauer and Schott (1993, p. 33-36). Scrum Unilateral increase in environmental stringency. As a direct test of importance of regulations on trade specialization, a set of simulations analyzes a unilateral reduction in unit emission for each conmtry. In addition to finese main variants, a number of ofiner sensitivity runs were undertaken Variations in elasticities of demand, productiorn, scale, labor supply, as well as difl‘erent marginal costs of abatement were analyzed These variations influence fine order of magnitude of fine trade effect in a predictable way,however, and do not change fine qualitative picture of fine results. Similarly, making abatement more expensive or introducing a substitution relationship between labor and emissions does not afi‘ect fine results noticeably. 6.3.2. Dependence of Results on Pre-NAFTA Trade Barriers The economic and environmental effects of fine scenarios are substantially driven by fine economic structure irn 1988 before trade liberalization. To interpret fine results, it is particularly noteworfiny finat pre-NAFT A trade barriers difi‘er substantially across sectors. Predictably, rrnost effects occur where barriers are highest Since, fine highest pre-NAFT A trade barriers tend to 229 be directed against primary and heavy industrial goods, finere is a certain bias in fine policy scenario towards a specialization in relatively polluting goods. This bias is less likely to exist if one wants to draw conclusions about trade in general. If pre-NAFT A trade barriers were fine same for each sector, national factor endowments and production functions would be fine exclusive drivers of fine induced trade specialization. Furfinermore, fine CGB model cannot analyze fine impact of regnnlatory difi‘erences between countries as such, because of fine equilibrium assumption. This is because sectoral profits are given in fine SAM, a higher assumed abatement expenditure would ornly lead to a re- calibration such finat fine additional costs would be compensated by a higher productivity of fine non-abatement capital. Therefore, fine model can only analyze fine impact of changes in abatement expenditures, not fine impact of fine existing absolute abatement levels. Factor endowments are important for fine economic specializatiorn of fine individual countries. However, factor endowments for production are not constant The availability of fine environment as a production factor can vary due to regulation. Effective production capital can be reduced by higher pollution abatement. Furfinermore, labor supply depends on wage rates and income, as well as fine healfil effect of changes in fine pollution level. In addition, fine production functiorns and, hence, economic efficiency in each sector vary among countries. Finally, fine welfare assessment of fine NAFTA scenario deviates from fine GDP figures. Welfare is based on three components. The first component, private consumption, is largely a leveraged GDP increase, because government cornsumption is fixed to its original level. The second component is leisure time, which is file inverse of fine change in labor supply. The finird component is fine induced effect of NAFTA on healfin. 230 6.4 Macroeconomic Effects of Policy Scenarios 6.4.1. Scenario 1: Full Trade Liberalization with Immobile Capital The abolition of trade barriers wifinin Norfin American has a positive impact on all finree econonnies, causing total annual GDP to increase by $40 bn (1988 dollars) both for internationally mobile and immobile capital. In relative terms, fine greatest winnes are Mexico and Canada wifin GDP increases of more than 2%, while U.S. GDP increased by 0.6 % In absolute terms, however, two thirds of fine benefits accrue to fine U.S., a quarter to Carnada, and only one tenfin to Mexico. The results are in line wifin the predictions of ofiner models on NAFTA (eg models summarized in CBC 1993, Kehoe and Kehoe 1995, Brown 1994). However, a comparison is made dificult by fine fact finat not all ofiner models have included fine efl‘ect of CAFT A. In fine U.S. and Canada, capital rents rise slightly more finan wages because of two factors. First, while fine model assumes a cornstant capital stock, labor supply irncreases because of higher wage rates. This supply increase dampens fine real wage increase. Second, fine demand for abatement capital increases following fine model-endogenous regulation tightening finat results from fine increased wealfil. In Mexico, fine gap between rents arnd wages is even larger, due to relative factor abundance. In terms of its production structure, Mexico is relatively labor scarce. The large number of workers in fine country is nnore than balanced out by a low rate of labor productivity". The results replicate fine Stolper-Samuelson fineorem that 5‘ Tlnisisonlyatfirstglanceincontradictiontomanyofinersmdies,whichdescribeMexicoasa labor-abundant country. These studies use a definition based on work hours rather, whilefine presentpaperlooksatthewagesum. 231 trade liberalization in a relatively capital-intensive country increases rents rrnore than wages. In Canada and fine U.S., finis factor works in fine opposite direction. Sectoral effects of fine scenario are also in line wifin fine findings of ofiner studies. Car manufacturing is expected to increase everywhere. Similarly, electronics irncreases, while textile and apparel growfin is only moderate. Irnportanfiy, in fine full liberalization scenario, petroleum production in Mexico increases substantially. This result is not universally present in ofiner models, finough some derive similar results (e. g. Brown et al. 1995, Sobarzo 1995). Since fine petroleum sector is partly excluded from NAFTA, some aufinors have presented nnodel simulations wifinout finis sector, others like in finis paper have assumed finat trade barriers irn finis area are also abolished. The consequences of finis assumption will be discussed furfiner below 6.4.2. Scenario 2: Full Trade Liberalization with Mobile Capital The possibility of transferring capital from one country to another changes fine nature of fine trade closure. Capital is transferred to fine country wifil fine highest rate of return. In finis fine model, capital flows are exclusively driven by divergent developments in rnorrninal interest rates. Since capital gains are relatively highest in Mexico, fine country experiences a high irnflow of capital from fine U.S. This capital inflow leads to a substantially higher GDP growfin (3.3% compared to 2.4% wifin immobile capital), and an even more substantial clnange in production volume (2.5% irnstead of 1.2%). F urfinermore, it reinforces fine industrial specialization of fine country. Despite fine higher GDP, private consumption in Mexico remains practically unchanged compared to Scenario 1, as fine profits of fine additional activity accrues to the Urnited States. Canada also experiences capital inflows from fine U.S. However, finey are insignificant The changes on fine U.S. side nnirror finose of Mexico, as GDP drops compared to fine scenario 232 witln immobile capital. However, due to fine large size of its economy, changes in fine U.S. are relatively smaller, wifin GDP gains shrinking from 0.64% to 0.61%. 6.4.3. Scenario 3: Leaving out the Petroleum Sector Unsurprisingly, fine benefits of a NAFTA scenario finat leaves out fine petroleum sector are less than in fine first two scenarios. There. is a noticeable reduction in fine trade benefits, mainly for Mexico but also for fine U.S. In fine case of immobile capital(Scenario 3a), Mexico’s GDP gain drops fi‘om 2.4% to 1.9%, finat of fine U.S. fiom 0.64% to 0.59%. Cannada remains practically unaffected, not least, because oil trade between Mexico and Canada is minimal. Neverfineless, fine oil sector in Mexico still grows strongly by 6% instead of 14% driven by indirect demand. Owing to fine capital intensity of fine sector, fine reduced welfare gains are borne slightly more by capital owners finan workers. For mobile capital (Scenario 3b), fine effects of fine scenario change even nnore dramatic for Mexico. Instead of a 3.3% GDP gain in Scenario 2, its economy increases only by 1.1%. This is notably due to a reversal in fine flow of capital, which is now leaving fine courntry causing accelerated growfin in Canada and fine United States instead. In filis case, fine oil sector even shrinks slightly. 6.4.4. Scenario 4: Unilateral Increase in Environmental Stringency A unilateral decrease in permissible emission factors in fine United States leads to a drop in GDP in fine country by 2.3%. The incidence of fine tighter regulations falls exclusively on wages (4.75%), because effective labor supply increases by 0.3% due to a large improvement in healfin. By contrast, capital actually benefits due to the demand for abatement equipment and fine increased labor supply (+3.16%). The U.S. economy finerefore becomes more labor- 233 intensive. The increased abatement costs finerefore imply a structural clnarnge away fiom pollutiorn intensive and capital intensive sectors. One can notice some countervailing increase in fine output of finese sectors in fine ofiner two courntries. However, Mexico and Canada do not sufi'ncienfiy benefit from fine reduced compefitiveness of fine U.S. in finese sectors to compensate finem for fine decrease in GDP of fineir main trading partrner. GDP shrinks by 0.3% bofin in Mexico and Canada Iffine unilateral increase in stringency takes place in a setting wifin intennationally rrnobile capital, fine burden on finese econorrnies is substantially higher. GDP shrinks by 1.1% in Mexico and by 0.8% irn Canada, because capital flows to fine U.S. to profit from fine irncreased return This flow is accompanied by a reversal irn fine structural change. The secondary effect ofcornnected capital markets causes structural charnges to be in parallel wifin finose offile United States. This change contrasts wifin fine case of immobile capital, where structnnral changes in fine ofiner countries move in fine opposite direction of finose in fine United States. The case of unilateral action in Canada is directly comparable, given adjustments for its smaller size. So is fine case of Mexico. GDP drops irn all finree countries. Howeve, in fine case of Mexico, low abatement costs and high extemalities actually lead to loss irn GDP finat is an order of magnitude smaller finan in fine ofiner two countries (0.2%). 234 6.5 Environmental Effects of Policy Scenarios 6.5.1. Scenario 1: Full Trade Liberalization with Immobile Capital W ' Wifinout tighter regulation, trade liberalization wifin immobile capital would sirnnply lead to higher emissions in Norfin America, if only because of economic growfin Due to fine increased efficiency in fine NAFTA area (allocation efi‘ect), fine growfin-induced pollution is less finan fine increase irn GDP. Neverfineless, bofin effects combined would yield an increase in emissions in fine U.S. of0.2, in Mexico of 1.2%, and in Canada of 1.8%. The compositionefi‘ect modifies fine results. In particular, Mexico shows a furfine increase in pollution of 2.2% because of economic specialization. This result means finat its relative pollution-intensity is increasing. To a much smaller extent, Canada also experiences a small positive composition efl‘ect of 0.2%. By contrast, fine value for fine United States is negative. The country specializes in clean sectors. As such, finis result gives support to fine poverty attraction hypofinesis, as fine poorer country attracts fine polluting industry. Alfinough fine induced pollution specialization is not large, Mexico would notice a 3.3% higher pollution level were it not for a substantial 1.8% reduction due to tighter regulation first is induced by fine increased income in the country. The inclusion of fine regulation efl‘ect even leads overall emissions in fine U.S. to drop by 0.6%, while finose of Canada stay cornstant, despite fine substantial economic growfin and a slight specialization in pollution-intensive production. 235 i f m 'v 11 The composition effect is robust to fine choice of pollutants. Virtually an identical picture emerges for sulfurdioxide (802), nitrogen dioxide (N02), volatile organic compournds (V CC), and total suspended particles (T SP). The U.S. shows slighfiy negative values. Those for Mexico are strongly positive, while values for Canada are slighfiy positive. However, carborn nnonoxide (c0) and small particles (PM10) do not fit the picture. co causes sigrn reversals for Canada and significantly lowers values for Mexico. PM10 even reverses signs for all countries. Some variation is to be expected simply because relative sectoral emission intensifies vary by pollutant. This effect is reinforced by fine dependence of fine composition efi‘ect on only a few crucial sectors. Management These induced changes in pollution are also evaluated in welfare terms. Simulations indicate that healfin (measured in changes in sick days) improves by 0.02% in fine U.S. arnd deteriorates by 0.09% in Mexico, while it is virtually unchanged in Canada Changing healfin levels afi‘ect welfare directly as one of its composite parts, and indirectly, because a lower number of sick days increases fine effective labor supply. Better healfin finerefore leads to a higher level of GDP. For fine simulation reported here, finese induced changes are small, but not completely negligible. They shift fine total benefits of the trade agreement up by over 3% for fine U.S., and down by more finan 3% for Mexico. These figures are exclusively based on fine extemality of particles alone. Ifone also aggregates fine effects of ofiner air pollutants based on toxicity weights, fine share of the extemality in fine overall welfare efi‘ect would be over 5% for bofin file U.S. and Mexico. 236 6.5.2. Scenario 2: Full Trade liberalization with Mobile Capital In scenario 2, which assumes full trade liberalization wifin internationally mobile capital, fine capital inflow to Mexico substantially increases fine pollution effect in fine country. Bofin a higher absolute level of economic activity and a greater economic specialization drive up fine pollution figures by more finan 2%. However, fine increased econonnic activity is not matched by a simultaneous increase in environmental stringency, because fine benefits to of fine capital inflow accrues to foreigners. This leaves private consumptiorn, fine driver of stricter regulations, practically unchanged. By contrast, in fine U.S. capital outflows reduce pollution levels, because economic changes in fine U.S. are fine reverse of finose in Mexico. Here, fine ecornomy contracts sliglnfiy, and fine country specializes more ill low polluting activities compared to fine scenario wifinout international capital mobility. However, fine relative changes are rafiner small. In fine case of mobile capital, fine induced environmental extemalities decrease Mexico’s welfare gain by more finan 8%. Wifin a toxicity-weighted index, extemalities would even reduce fine trade gains by nearly 14%. For Mexico, the additional benefits of capital nnobility in terms of higher GDP are outweighed by fine welfare loss due to higher pollution However, filis cannot be seen as an indictment of trade liberalization as such, because fine overall welfare gains are still solidly positive (+22%). The environmental damage fiom trade liberalizatiorn would have to be very substantial to overwhelm fine welfare benefits in terms of lniglne economic growfin. 237 6.5.3. Scenario 3: Leaving out the Petroleum Sector In determining fine overall pollution effect, fine oil sector plays a crucial role - because of its high pollution-intensity and its importance, in particular for Mexican exports. Bxempting fine petroleum sector fiom trade liberalization implies for Mexico a lower scale efi‘ect a lower composition effect, and a reduced regulation effect For immobile capital, fine net impact on Mexico’s pollution level remains only a finird of fine full liberalization case (+07%). However, no sign change occurs anywhere. Despite fine restrictions on trade, fine results are robust in finis aspect, largely because fine oil sector in Mexico still expands. In file case of mobile capital, changes are more significant. The capital outflow leads Mexican emissions drop by more finan 1%, instead of increasing by nearly 4%. The sharply reduced scale efl‘ect and a substantially reduced composition efl’ect (3% less) dominate finis change. By contrast, fine net emissions reduction in fine U.S. is less strorng, while Canada’s emissions even increase by 0.4%. The scenarios therefore indicate finat fine resultsare sensitive to a sirngle sector. This sensitivity can also be measured in fine fnnll trade liberalization scenario if ennissiorn changes due to fine petroleum sectorare set to zero. This would substantially afi'ect fine compositiorn effect. For Mexico, finis modification would imply a net emission efi’ect finat is reduced by 1.8% in fine case of immobile capital and 3.7% inn fine case of mobile capital. In taking out fine efi'ects of finis one sector, environmental benefits are eifiner strongly positive or insignificant, as fine results are now dominated by fine influence of tighter regulations. 238 6.5.4. Scenario 4: Unilateral Increase in Environmental Stringency Sirnnulating fine unilateral increase in regulatory stringency in one connntry is fine nnost direct test on fine pollution haven hypothesis.” In fine regulating country, fine pollution reductiorn is noticeably higher than what would be expected by fine regulation effect only. Next to fine contracting GDP, fine composition effect plays a substantial role, because as production moves away from abatement and pollution-intensive goods. In general most of finis reflects actual changes in consumption. Relatively little of fine composition efi‘ect is counterbalanced by concomitant increases in pollution-intensity in partnner countries. Neverfineless, in fine case of immobile capital trading partners experience an increase in pollution. This outcome is essentially fine result of more lax regulations following a decreased private consumption. The overall evaluation of a unilateral regulatory step depends, of course, on fine magnitude of fine GDP and healfin changes, which move in opposite directions. While healfin benefits substantially reduce fine welfare costs of decreased output, in fine U.S. and Canada arnd welfare decreases by 0.3, respectively 0.8%. By contrast, in Mexico a unilateral tightening of environmental stringency provides significant welfare gains of 1%. Healfin benefits are large, while GDP reductions are quite small in fine first place, due to improved labor productivity and fine low level of abatement expenditures. As a variant of file calculating fine efi‘ect of increasing environmental stringency unilaterally, one can derive for each country how large fine regulation elasticity needs to be for ”Itisofnopracticalconscquenccwhetherfinisscenarioisimposcdonabenchmarkwifilor without trade barriers in place. 5‘ This can be seen by transforming it into U = (M‘HH’y , where [31 = 1, and (l-Bn = 11. The allocation consequence ofy is zero, and could be left out. 239 trade liberalization to be environmentally beneficial. (Evidenfiy, finis value will difi'er by type of pollutant). In fine case of fine two scenarios wifin full NAFTA trade liberalization finis finreshold value would be very low for fine U.S., at about 0.2; for Canada, fine value is somewhat lower finan 1. Mexico, by contrast, would need values between 1.5 and 2. However, finere may be good reasons to believe finat fine elasticity in Mexico as a response to NAFTA is higher finarn irn fine ofiner two countries due to irnstitutional cooperation between fine U.S. and Mexico (Runge 1994). The country appears under-regulated, and is subject to external and interrnal pressures to change finis situation. Variations in fine form of policy functions (e. g. by making it dependent on wages) do not influence finese results notably. 6.6. Conclusions Bcononnic modeling in finis paper shows that fine incorporation of induced regulation- setting plays a crucial role in analyzing fine environmental impact of trade liberalizatiorn. Under a broad range of trade liberalization scenarios in Norfin America, fine environmental situation improves not simply in general but also in each individual country. This occurs despite fine fact finat fine pre-NAFT A structure of trade protection biases fine result towards an exparnsiorn of pollution-intensive sectors. The, fine net efi‘ect of fine scenarios depends on a relatively limited number of factors. For NAFTA, changes in fine petroleum sector are central. However, fine link between regulation setting and disposable income finat is employed in fine model must not be interpreted as being automatic and instantaneous. The functional form can at best represent a proxy for a complicated political process finat hinges on a large number of factors. The responsiveness of institutions depends certainly on fine degee of democracy in fine country at hand. Furfinermore, income distribution or, more generally, fine distnhution of political power will modify fine link between aggregate wealfin and regulation setting. 240 Neverfineless, contrary to much of fine existing literature, fine fully integrated pollutiorn efi‘ects analysis demonstrated here points to a fundamental redirection in fine trade and environment debate. In spite of difi‘erences in environmental stringency among countries, trade and environmental interests can be allies. Therefore, environmental concerns are best focused on transforming fine institutions of fine home country and finat of fine trading partrners, not on restricting trade wifil institutionally weak countries. Consequently, fine essential researcln question corncems fine process finat leads to institutional changes. This paper could only touch on finis issue vaguely, and has to rely on a more or less plausible approximation. Next to deriving empirical evidence to fine country transformation hypofinesis, fine simulation results are consistent wifin conventional findings irn fine literature. First, finey reproduce the consensus arnswer on fine classical trade and environment question Due to fineir relatively low cost impact, environmental policies matter only marginally inn industrial location. The effect of stricter environmental regulations on trading partners depends crucially on fine assumed level of capital mobility. Second, in line wifin fine poverty attraction hypofinesis, simulations show finat wifinin fine NAFTA area dirty industry tends to move to fine poorer country (Mexico). However, finis conclusion depends strongly on developments irn fine oil sector. Third, fine simulations show fine importance of including extemalities into fine analysis. This inclusion leads to a noticeable revision in fine overall welfare assessment of trade liberalization. Furfinermore, it can be shown finat for an under-regulated conmtry like Mexico, a urnilateral increase in regulations is possible that would allow for significant welfare improvements, even if sectors work in an internationally competitive environment 241 BIBLIOGRAPHY Adams, G. F., M. Alanis, and A. B. del Rio. “The Mexico-United States Free Trade and Investment Area Proposal: A Macroeconometric Evaluation of Impacts on Mexico”. Journal of Policy Modeling 14(1), 1992: 99-119. Afsaln, S., B. Laplante and D. Wheeler. ”Controlling Industrial Pollution: A New Paradigrn, " World Bank, Policy Research Department Working Paper, 1996. Ahmad, Y. 8. El Serafy, and E. Lutz (editors). Environmental Accounting for Sustainable Development, Washington, DC, World Bank, 1989. American Lung Association. Dollars and cents: The economic and health benefits of potential particulate matter reductions in the United States. Washingtorn, DC, 1995. Anderson, K. “The Entwining of Trade Policy wifin Environmental and Labour Standards.” Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei: Working Paper 39, 1995. Arat, 2. F. “Democracy and Economic Development: Modernization Theory Revisited”. Comparative Politics (October), 1988: 21-36. Arden-Clarke, C. “International Trade, GATT, and fine Environment”. WWF Intemational Discussion Paper, 1992a Arden-Clarke, C. “Soufil-Norfin Terms of Trade, Environmental Protection arnd Sustainable Development”. WWF International Discussion Paper, 1992. Armington, P. ”A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production" International Monetary Fund Stafl' Papers, Vol. XVI, No. 1, 1969:159-176. Ashworfin, J. and I Papps. “Equity in European Community Pollution Control”. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 20(1), 1991: 46-54. Audley, J. “Environmental 'Window Dressing' and NAFTA”. In: North American Free Trade Agreement: Opportunities and Challenges, edited by Fatenni, K. New York: St Martin's Press, 1993: 252-270. Ballard, C. L. “The Marginal Eficiency Cost of Redistribution”. American Economic Review 78(5), 1988: 1019-1033. Ballard, 0, D. Fullerton, J. Shoven and J. Whalley. A General Equlibrium Model jbr Tax Policy Evaluation, Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1985. Ballard, C. L. and S.G. Medema “The Marginal Emciency Efi‘ects of Taxes arnd Subsidies in fine Presence of Extemalities”. Journal of Public Economics 52, 1993: 199-216. 242 Baumol, W. J. and W. Oates. “The Theory of Environmental Policy ”, Englewood Clififs: Prentic Hall, 1988. Beglnirn, J ., and M Potier. “Efi‘ects of Trade Liberalisation on fine Environment in fine Manufacturing Sector”. The World Economy, Vol. 20(4) 1997: 435-456. Beghin, J ., D. Roland-Holst and D. van der Mensbrugghe, “Trade Liberalization arnd fine Environment in fine Pacific Basin: Coordinated Approaches to Mexicarn Trade arnd Environment Policy”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 1995 (77): 778-85. Beglnin, J., D. Roland-Holst, and van der Mensbrugghe. “Trade and Pollution Lirnkages: Piecemenal Reform and Optimal Intervention”, Canadian Journal of Economics, 1997(30): 442-55. Bergnarn, L. “General Equilibrium Effects of Environmental Policy: A CGE-Modeling Approach”. Environmental and Resource Economics 1, 1991. Bhagwati, J. “The Case for Free Trade”. Scientific American (November) 1993: 42-49. Birdsall, N. and D. Wheeler. “Trade Policy and Industrial Pollution in Latin America: Where are fine Pollution Havens?” In: International Trade and the Environment, edited by Low, P. Washington: World Bank, 1992: 159-168. Blackhurst, R “International Trade and Domestic Environmental Policies in a Growing World Economy”. In: International Relations in a Changing World, edited by Blackhurst, R, et al. Geneva: Syfinoff -Leide, 1977: 341-364. Bommer, R and G. G. Schulze. “Econonnic Integration and Environmental Policy: Does NAFTA Increase Pollution?” University of Konstanz, Dept. of Econonnics arnd Statistics, 1996. Boumarn, M “Do Pollution Abatement Costs Induce Direct Foreign Investments? Evidence for Germany”. University of Amsterdam (nnimeo), 1996. Boyd, R and N. Uri. “The Cost of Improving fine Quality of fine Environment”. Journal of PolicyModeling 13(1) 1991: 115-140. Brander, J. and P. Krugman. “A 'Reciprocal Dumping’ Model of International Trade”. Journal of International Economics 15, 1983: 313-321. Broad, R “The Poor and fine Environment: Friends of Foes?”. World Development 22(6), 1994: 811-822. Brown, D. K. “Properties of Computable General Equilibrium Models wifin Mornopolistic Competition and Foreign Direct Investment”. Tufts University, 1992. Brown, D. K, A. V. Deardorfi~ and R M Stern. “A Norfin American Free Trade Agreement: Analytical Issues and Computational Assessment”. World Economy 15(1), 1992. Burnniaux, J. M, J. P. Martin, G. Nicoletti, and J. Oliveira-Marfins. “GREEN- A mulfisector, multi-region dynamic general equilibrium model for quantifying fine costs of curbing C02 emissions: a technical manual”. OECD Bcononnics Department Working Papers 116. Paris: OECD, 1992. ' Chapman, D. “Environmental Standards and International Trade in Automobiles and Copper: fine Case for a Social Tarifi”. Natural Resources Journal, 1991. 243 Chichilrnisky, G. “Norfin-Soufin Trade and fine Global Environment”. American Economic Review, September 1994: 851-74. Clopper Almon/Inforum Industrial Efi'ects of a Free Trade Agreement Between Mexico arnd fine USA U. S. Department of Labor. 1990. Cole, MA, A. J. Rayner, and J. M. Bates. “The Environmental Impact of fine Uruguay Round”. CREDIT Research Paper No. 97/20, Urniversity of Nottingham, 1997. Collins, C. O. and S. L. Scott. “Air Pollution in fine Valley of Mexico”. The Geographical Review 83(2), 1993: 120-133. Congressional Budget Office (CBO) “Estimating fine Efi‘ects of NAFTA: An Assessment of fine Economic Models and Ofiner Empirical Studies”. Washington, D. C. 1993. Conrad, K. and M. Schroeder. “Choosing Environmental Policy Instruments Using General Equilibrium Models”. Journal of Policy Modeling 15(5&6), 1993: 521-543. Copeland, B. R “Pollution Content Tariffs, Environmental Rent Shifting, and fine Control of Cross-Border Pollution”. Journal of International Economics 40, 1996: 459-476. Copeland, B. R and M. S. Taylor. “Norfin-Soufin Trade and fine Environment”. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 1994: 755-787. Copeland, B. R and M. S. Taylor. “Trade and Environment: A Partial Synfinesis”. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 77 (August), 1995: 765-771. Cropper, M and W. Oates. “Environmental Econonnics: A Survey”. Journal of Economic Literature 30, 1992: 675-750. Cumberland, J. H. and B. N. Stam. “Empirical Results from Application of fine Input-Output Models to Environmental Problems”. In: Advances in Input-Output Analysis, edited by Poenske, K. R and Skolka, J. V. Cambridge: Ballinger, 1976. D'Arge, R “International Trade, Domestic Income, and Environmental Controls”. In: Managing the Environment, edited by Kneese, A. New York: Praeger, 1974. Dalnl, R A. “Polyarchy, Participation and Opposition”. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1971. Daly, H. E. "The Perils of Free Trade”. Scientific American, 1993 : 50-57. Daly, H. E. and J. B. Cobb. “For fine Common Good: Redirecting fine Econorrny toward Community and a Sustainable Future”. Boston: Beacon Press, 1989. Dasgupta, Susnnita, Ashoka Mody, Subhendu Roy and David Wheeler, 1995, “Environmental Regulation and Development: .A Cross-Country Empirical Analysis”. World Bank, Policy Research Department Working Paper, No. 1448, April de Bruyrn, S., J. van den Bergh and H. Opschoor. “Empirical Investigations in Envirornrnental- Ecornorrnic Relationships”. Discussion Paper 95-150. Tinbergen Institute: Free University Amsterdam. TT, 1995. Dean, J. Trade. “The Environment: A Survey of fine Literature”. In: International Trade and the Environment, edited by Low, P. Washington, D. C., World Bank, 1992: 15-28. 244 Despotakis, K A. and A C. Fisher. “Energy in a Regional Ecornorrny: A Computable General Equilibrium Model for Califorrnia”. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15, 1988: 313-330. Dessus, S. and M. Bussolo. “Is finere a Trade-Ofi’ between Trade Liberalisation and Pollutiorn Abatement in Costa Rica? A Computable General Equilibrium Assessment”. Journal of Policy Modeling 20(1), 1995: 11-31. Dockery, D. and et al. “An Association Between Air Pollution and Mortality in Six U. S. Cities”. The New England Journal ofMedicine 329(24), 1993: 1753-59. Duerksen, C. and HI. “Environmental Regulations and fine Location of Industries: An Irntemational Perspective”. Columbia Journal of World Business 15, 1980: 15-68. Esty, D. C. and B. S. Gentry. “Foreign Investment, Globalisation and Environment”. In: Globalisation and Environment: Preliminary Perspectives, edited by OECD, Paris: 1998. Esty, D. B. “Greening fine GATT: Trade, Environment and fine Future Washington, DC: Institute for International Econorrnics, 1994. European Commission. “Impact of Environmental Policies on Electricity Generating Costs”. Brussels: European Commission, D. G. XI., Report No. 2482, 1994. Forsund, F. R “Input-Output Models, National Econonnic Models, arnd fine'Environment”. In: Handbook of Natural Resource and Energy Economics, edited by Kneese, A and Sweeney, J. V. Amsterdam: Norfin Holland, 1985: 325-341. GATT, Trade and fine Environment, in GATT: International Trade 1990-91, Vol. 1 (Part III). 1992. Goldemberg, J. “Energy, Techrnology, Development”. Ambio 21(1), 1992: 14-17. Goulder, L. and B. Bichengreen, ”Trade Liberalization in General Equilibrium: Intertenporal and Inter-Industry Bfi’ects". Canadian Journal of Economics, 25(2), May1992: 253-280. Gray, W. B. and RJ. Shadbegian. “Environmental Regnnlation and Manufacturing Productivity at fine Plant Leve ”. Working Paper No. 4321. Cambridge, MA: Natiornal Bureau of Economic Research, 1993. Griffifin, C. A. “NAFTA, Sustainable Development, and fine Environment: Mexico's Approac ”. Journal of Environment and Development 2( 1), 1993: 193-203. Grossman, G. and A. Krueger. "Economic Growfin and fine Environment, " Quarterly Journal of Economics, May, 1995: 353-377 Hackrnanrn, J. “International Trade in Waste Materials”. Review of International Trade and Development 29, 1994. Harris, N. and S. Puente. “Environmental Issues in fine Cities of Development: The Case of Mexico City”. Journal of International Development 2(4), 1990: 500-532. Hartman, Raymond, Mainul Huq and David Wheeler, ”Why Paper Mills Clean Up: Detemninants of Pollution Abatement in Four Asian Countries”. World Bank, Policy Research Department Working Paper 1710, 1997. 245 I Hartman, Raymond, Manjula Singh and David Wheeler, "The Cost of Air Pollution Abatement”. Applied Economics (forthcoming) Hazilla, M. and R J. Kopp. “The Social Cost of Environmental Quality Regulations: A General Equilibrium Analysis”. Journal of Political Economy, 1990: 853-873. Summers, R and R Heston, “The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988” The Quarterly Journal of Econonnics 106(2), 1991. Hettige, H, R Lucas and D. Wheeler, "The Toxic Intensity of Industrial Production: Global Patterns, Trends and Trade Policy". American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 82, 1992: 478-481. Hettige, H, P. Martin, M. Sirngln and D. Wheeler. ”IPPS: The Industrial Pollution Projection System”. World Bank, Policy Research Department Working Paper, February 1995. Hettige, H., M Huq, S. Pargal and D. Wheeler. ”Determinants of Pollution Abatement in Developing Countries: Evidence from Soufin and Soufineast Asia”. World Development, December 1996. Hettige, H, M. Singh, S. Pargal and D. Wheeler. "Formal and Irnforrnal Regulation of Industrial Pollution: Evidence from fine US and Indonesia". World Bank Economic Review, Fall 1997. Hoeller, P., A. Dean, and J. Nicolaison. “A Survey of Studies of fine Costs of Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions”. Working Papers No. 89. Paris: OECD Dept of Economics and Statistics, 1990. Hufoauer, G. C. and J. J. Schott. North American Free Trade: Issues and Recommendations, Washington, D. C. Institute for International Econonnics, 1992. Hufbauer, G. C. and J. J. Schott. NAFTA. An Assessment. Washington, D. C. Institute for International Economics, 1993. Inglehard, R Culture Shifl in Advanced Industrial Society. Princeton: Princeton Universtiy Press, 1990. Irnura, H, R Fujikura, T. Mizuno and H. Shiratsuchi. “Study on fine Trade Balance of Embodied Energy wifin Special Regard to fine Asia-Pacific Region”. Journal of Global Environment Engineering 2, 1997: 39-49. Jafi'e, A B., S. R Peterson, P. R Portney and R N. Stavins. “Environmental Regulatiorn and fine Competitiveness of U. S. Manufacturing: What does fine Evidence Tell Us?". Journal of Economic Literature 33, 1995: 132-163. Jha, V., Vossenaar, R, and Zarrilli, S. Ecolabelling and International Trade. Discussiorn Papers. UNCT AD. UNCTAD. 70, 1993. John, A. and R Pecchenino, 1992. ”An Overlapping Generations Model of Growfin and fine Environment". Department of Economics, Michigan State University (mimeo. ). Jones, R W. “A Three-Factor Model in Theory of Trade and ' ry”. In: Trade, Balance of Payment and Growth: Essays in Hor of Charles P. Kindleberger, edited by Bhagwati, J. N. Amsterdam: Norfin Holland, 1971: 3-21. 246 Jorgenson, D. W. and Wilcoxen Peter Environmental Regulation arnd U. S. Economic Growfin RAND Journal of Economics 21, 1990: 314-340. Kalt, J. P. “The Impact of Domestic Environmental Regulatory Policies on U. S. International Competitiveness”. In: International Competitiveness, edited by Spence, A M and Hazard, H. A. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company, 1988, Kehoe, P. J., and T. J Kehoe. Modeling North American Economic Integration. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1995. Kennedy, P. W. “Equilibrium Pollution Taxes in Open Econonnies wifin Imperfect Competition”. Discussion Paper 93-01. University of Victoria, British Columbia, 1993. Krutilla, K “Environmental Regulation in an Open Economy”. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 20, 1991: 127-244. Kummer, K. “Transboundary Movements of Hazardous Wastes at fine Irnterface of Environment and Trade”. Environment and Trade. UNEP. 7, 1994. Kwan, C. E. and S. R Johnson. “Regulation of Extemalities in an Open Econonny. Ecological Economics 5, 1992: 251-265. Leamer, E. E. Book Review: Norfin American free trade: Issues and recommendations by Gary Clyde Hufbauer and Jeffrey J. Schott, 1992. Journal of Economic Literature 31, 1991: 1982-1983. Lee, H. and D. Roland-Holst “The Environmental and Welfare Implications of Trade arnd Tax Policy” Journal of Development Economics 53, 1997 : 65-82. Leonard, H. J. Pollution and the Struggle for World Product. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1988. Levinson, A. “Environmental Regulations and Manufacturer's Location Choices: Evidence from fine Census of Manufactures”. Journal of Public Economics 62, 1996: 5-29. Levy, D. L. “The Environmental Practices and Performance of Transnational Corporatiorns”, Transnational Corporations. 4 (l), 1995. Lopez, R “The Environment as a Factor of Production: The Effect of Economic Growfin and Trade Liberalization”. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 27 (September), 1994: 163-184. Low P.. “Trade Measures and Environmental Quality: The Implications for Mexico's Exports”. In: International Trade and the Environment, edited by Low, P. Washington, D. C. World Bank, 1992: 105-120. Low P. and A. Yeats. “Do 'Dirty' Industries Migrate?” In: International Trade and the Environment, edited by Low, P. Washington, D. C. World Bank, 1992. Lucas, R E. B., D. Wheeler, and H. Hettige. “Economic Development, Environnmental Regulation and fine Interrnational Migration of Toxic Industrial Pollution: 1960-1988”. Irn: International Trade and the Environment, edited by Low, P. Washington, D. C. World Bank, 1992: 67-86. Mani, M "Environmental Tariffs on Polluting Imports: An Empirical Study, " Environmental and Resource Economics 7, 1996: 391 -41 1 247 Markandya, A. and C. Costanza (editors) Environmental Accounting: A Review of fine Currend Debate, New York, UN Environment and Econorrnics Unit, 1993. Markusen, J. R Intennal Extemalities and Optimal Tax Structures. Journal of International Economics 5, 1975: 15-29. Markusen, J. R “Factor Movements and Commodity Trade as Complements”. Journal of International Economics 17, 1983: 335-354. McConnell, V. and R M. Schwab. “The Impact of Environmental Regulation on Industry Location Decisions: The Motor Vehicle Industry”. Land Economics 66(1), 1990: 67-81. McGuire, M. Regulatiorn, Factor Rewards, and Interrnational Trade. Journal of Public Economics 17, 1982: 335-354. McLeery, R K “An Intertemporal, Linked Macroeconomic CGE Model of fine United States and Mexico Focussing on Demographic Change and Factor Flows”. In: Applied General Equilibrium Assessment of North American Free Trade, edited by Shiells, C. and Francois, J. Cambridge Universty Press, 1993. Merrifreld, J. D. “The Impact of Selected Abatement Strategies on Transnational Pollution, fine Terms of Trade, and Factor Rewar ”. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15, 1988: 259-284. Molina, D. J. “A Comment on whefiner Maquiladoras are in Mexico for Low Wages or to Avoid Pollution Abatement Costs”. Journal of Environment and Development 2(1), 1993: 221-241. Monty, R L. “Beyond Environmental Compliance: Business Strategies for Competitive Advantage”. Environmental Finance, 1991 : 3-1 1. Morris, D. “Free Trade: The Great Destroyer”. The Ecologist 20(5), 1990: 190-195. Motta, M. and J. F. Thisse. ”Minimum Quality Standards as an Environmental Policy. Domestic an International Effects". Nota di Lavoro 20, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, 1993. Mumme, S. P. “Clearing fine Air. Environmental Reform in Mexico”. Environment 33(10): 6- 1 l, 1991. ' Mundell, R A. “International Trade and Factor Mobility”. American Economic Review 47, 1957: 321-355. Murrell, P. and R Rytennan. “A Mefinodology for Testing Comparative Ecornorrnic Theories: Theory and Application to East-West Environmental Policies”. Journal of Comparative Economics 15, 1991: 582-601. Nestor, D. V. and C. A. Pasurka “Environment-Economic Accounting and Indicators of the Economic Importance of Environmental Protection Activities”. Washington, D. C. U. S. Environmental Protection Agency, 1993. Newman, R J. and D. H. Sullivan. “Econometric Analysis of Business Impacts on Industrial Location: What Do We Know, and How Do We Know It?”. Journal of Urban Economics 23, 1988: 215-234. 248 Nicolaison, J. and P. Hoeller. “Econonnics and fine Environment: A Survey of Issues and Policy Options”. Working Papers 82. Paris: OECD Dept of Economics and Statistics, 1990. O’Connor, D. “Managing fine Environment wifin Rapid Industrialisation: Lessons from fine East Asian Experience” Paris: OECD Development Centre, 1994. OECD (ed). Globalisation and Environment: Preliminary Perspectives. Paris: OECD., 1997. OECD. Eco-Labelling: Actual Efl'ects of Selected Programmes. OECD/GD(97) 105. Paris: OECD, 1997a OECD: Experience wifin fine Use of Trade Measures in fine Convention on Intematiornal Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora (CITES). OECD/GD(97) 106. Paris: OECD, 1997b. Ohlirn, B. “Interregional and Intennational Trade”. Cambridge, 1935. Ostro, B. D. “Air Pollution and Morbidity Revisited: A Specification Test”. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 14, 1987: 87-98. Palmer, K, W. Oates and P. R Portney. “Tightening Environmental Standards: The Benefit- Cost or fine No-Cost Paradigm?” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9(4), 1995: 119- 132. Pargal, S. and D. Wheeler, 1996, ”Infonnal Regulation in Developing Countries: Evidence from Indonesia". Journal of Political Economy, December. Pearson, C. “Implications for fine Trade and Investment of Developing Countries of United States Environmental Controls”, New York: UNCT AD, 1976. Pearson, C. “Environmental Standards, Industrial Relocation, and Pollutiorn Havens”. Im Multinational Corporations, Environment, and the Third World: Business Matters, edited by Pearson, C. Durham: Duke University Press, 1987: 113-128. Peltzrnan, S. Toward “A More General Theory of Regulation”. Journal of law and Economics 19, 1976: 211-240. Perrorni, C. and R M. Wigle. “International Trade and Environmental Quality: How Important are fine Linkages?” Canadian Journal of Economics, 1995. Pireddu, G. “Evaluating External Costs and Benefits from a Cleaner Environment in a Stylised CGE Model”. Working Paper 61.96. Fondazione ENI Enrico Mattei, 1996. Polo, C. and F. Sancho. “An Analysis of Spain's Integration into fine EEC”. Journal of Policy Modeling 15(2), 1993: 157-178. Porter, M. A “America's Green Strategy”. Scientific American 168, April 1991. Porter, M. A. and C. van der Linde. “Toward a New Conception of fine Environment- Competitiveness Relationship”. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9(4), 1995: 97-118. Radetzki, M. ”Economic Growfin and Environment”. In: Low, Patrick, eds, International Trade and the Environment, edited by P. Low, World Bank Discussion Paper 159, 1992: 121-134. ' Rauscher, M. “On Ecolocgical Dumping”. Venice: Fondazione ENI Enrico Mattei. Working Paper 29. 93., 1993. 249 Reinert, K, D. Roland-Holst and C. Shiells. “Social Accounts and fine Structure of fine North American Economy”. Economic systems Research 5(3), 1993: 295-326. Rhee, J. J. and J. A. Miranowski. “Determination of Income, Productiorn, arnd Employment under Pollution Control: An Input-Output Approach”. Review of Economics and Statistics 64, 1984: 146-150. Robisorn, H D. “Industrial Pollution Abatement: The Impact on fine Balance of Trade”. Canadian Journal ofEconomics 21(1), 1988: 187-199. Rock, M T. “Pollution Intensify of GDP and Trade Policy, Can the World Bank be Wrorng?” World Development 24, 1996: 471-479. Roland-Holst, D., K. Reinert, and C. Shiells. “Norfin American Trade Liberalization and fine Role of Nontarifl‘ Barriers” In: Applied General Equilibrium Assessment of North American Free Trade, edited by Shiells, C. and J. Francois, Cambridge. Carnbrdige University Press, 1994. Ronnieu, I., H. Weitzenfeld and J. Finkelman. “Urban Air Pollution in Latin America and fine Caribbean”. World Health Statistics Quarterly 43, 1990: 153-167. Rutledge G. and C. Vogan “Pollution Abatement and Control Expenditures 1972-92,” Survey of Current Business, May 1994, .36-49 Rybczynski, T. M “Factor endowment and relative commodity prices” Economica(22), 1955: 336-341. ' Scherp, J. and M Suardi. “Trade and Environment”. European Economy. Reports and Studies 3, 1997: 133-171. Schimmelpfennig, D. “An Empirical Investigation of fine Capital-Environrnent Tradeofi”. Washington: Economic Research Service. Research and Technology Divisiorn, 1992. Selden, T. and D. Song. ”Environmental Quality and Development: Is Thee a Kuzrnets Curve for Air Pollution Emissions?” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 27, 1994: 147-162. Selden, T. and D. Song. "Neoclassical Growfin, fine J Curve for Abatement, and fine Inverted U Curve for Pollution" Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29, 1995: 162-168. Shafik, N. “Economic Development and Environmental Quality: An Econometric Analysis”. Oxford Economic Papers 46, 1994: 757-773. Shelbume, R C. “The Norfin American Free Trade Agreement: Comparison wifin Soufinern EC Enlargement.” In: North American Free Trade Agreement. Opportunities and Challenges, edited by F atenni, K. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1993: 43-61. Shiells, C. and Reinert, K. “Amnington Models arnd Terms-of Trade Effects: Some Econometric Evidence for Norfin America” Canadian Journal of Economics 26(2), 1993: 299-3 16. Shiells, C., Roland-Holst, D., and Reinert, K “Modeling a Norfin American Free Trade Area: Estimation of Flexible Functional Fonrns”. Weltwirtschafliches Archiv 1993: 55-57. 250 Shoven, J. and Whalley, J. Applying General Equilibrium. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992. Shrybman, 8. “International Trade and fine Environment: An Environmental Assessment of fine General Agreement on 'T'arifl's and Trade”. The Ecologist 20(1), 1990: 30-34. Siebert, H “Spatial Aspects of Environmental Econorrnics”. In: Handbook of Natural Resource and Energy Economics, edited by Kneese, A and J. Sweeney, New York: North Holland, 1985. Siebert, H, Eichberger, J ., Gronych, R, and Pefinig, R Trade and Environment: A Theoretical Enquiry, Amsterdam: Elesevier, 1980. Snnifin, S. “Taxation and fine Environment: A Survey.” Fiscal Studies 13(4): 21-57, 1992. Snnifin, V. K and Espinosa, J. A. “Environment and Trade Policies: Some Mefinodological Lessons”. Discussion. Paper 96-18. Washington, D. C. Resources for fine Future, 1996. Sobarzo, H. E. “A General Equilibrium Analysis of Gains from Trade for fine Mexican Economy of a Norfin American Free Trade Agreement”. In: Applied General Equilibrium Assessment of North American Free Trade, edited by Shiells, C. and J. Francois, Carnbrdige University Press, 1994. Sorsa, P. “Competitiveness and Environmental Standards. Some Exploratory Results.” Policy Research Working Paper 1249. Washington: The World Bank, 1994. Srinivasarn, T. N. and J. Whalley, eds., General Equilibrium Trade Policy Modeling, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1986. Stafl‘ord, H A “Environmental Protection and Industrial Location”. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 75(2), 1985: 227-240. Stevens, C. “The Environmental Efl'ects of Trade.” World Economy 16(4), 1993: 439-451. Stolper W. F., and P. A. Samuelson: “Protection and Real Wages”. Review of Economic Studies 9, 1941: 58-73. Stigler, G. “The Theory of Ecornorrnic Regulation”. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2, 1971: 3-21. Strutt, A. and K. Anderson. “Will Trade Liberalization Harm fine Environment? The Case of Indonesia to 2020”. Seminar Paper 98-04. Centre for International Econonnic Studies, University of Adelaide, 1998. - Syrquin, M. ."Pattems of Structural Change, " in Handbook of Development Economics. 1, edited by Chenery, Hand T. N. Srinivasan Amsterdam: Norfin-Holland, 1989. Tobey, J. A. The Efi'ects of Domestic Environmental Policies on Patterns of World Trade: An Empirical Test Kyltlos 43(2): 191-209, 1990. Tudini, A, ”Trade and Environment: The Issue of Process and Production Mefinods, " Working Paper, Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, 1993. Ulph, A, ”The Choice of Environmental Policy Instruments and Strategic Intemational Trade, " University of Soufinarnptorn, October 1990. 251 Ulph, A “Environmental Policy and Interrnational Trade - Survey of Recent Economic Analysis” Working Paper 53.94, Fondazione ENI Enrico Mattei, 1994. UNCT AD Secretariat Trade, Environment and Development Aspects of Establishing and Operating Eco-Labelling Programmes. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. GE. 95-51079, 1995. US Bureau of fine Census, “Pollution Abatement Costs and Expenditures, 1993”, Current Industrial Reports MA200(93)-1, Washingtorn, December. 1994. U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Census, Manufactureres ’ Pollution Abatement Capital Expenditures and Operating Costs, 1988a. U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Census, Annual Survey ofManufacturers 1988b. van Beers, C. and van den Berg, J. “An Empirical Multi-Courntry Analysis of fine Impact of Environmental Regulations on Foreigrn Trade Flows”. Working Paper 44.96. Fondaziorne ENI Enrico Mattei, 1996. van der Ploeg, F. and de Zeeuw, A International Aspects of Pollution Control. Environmental and Resource Economics 2: 117-139, 1992. Victor, P. A Pollution: Economy and Environment, Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1972. Walter, L, 1973, “The Pollution Content of American Trade3. Western Econorrnic Journal 11: 67-70. Walter, I. and Ugelow, J. L. Environmental Policies in Developing Countries. Ambio 8(2-3): 102-108, 1979. Warhurst, R And Isnor, R “Environmental Issues for Developing Conmfiies Arising fiom Liberalised Trade in fine rrnining Industries”, Natural Resources Forum 20, 1996 : 27-35. Whalley, J. The Interface between Environmental and Trade Policy. The Economic Jounral 101,1991: 180-189. Wheeler, D. "The Econonnics of Industrial Pollution Control: An Intemational Perspective, " 1991, World Bank, Industry and Energy Department Working Paper, No. 60, January. 1991 Wheeler, D. and Martin, P. Prices, Policies and fine Intematiornal Difl'usion of Clean Technology: The Case of Wood Pulp Production. In: International Trade and the Environment, edited by Low, P., Washington, D. C., World Bank, 1992, p. 197-224. Wheeler, D. and Mody, A. Intemational Investment Location Decisions. The Case of U. S. Firms. Journal of International Economics 33: 57-76, 1992. Wong, Kar-Yiu, ”Are International Trade and Factor Mobility Substitutes?, " Journal of International Economics, 21(1/2): 25-44, August, 1986. World Bank, World Development Report I 992, Washington, D. C., 1992. World Resources Institute. World Resources: A Report. New York Basic Books 1986. 252 Xepappedas, A, and E. Amry: Some Empirical Implicaions of fine Relationship Between Environmental Quality and Econonnic Development. Environmental and Resource Economics 11, 1998: 93-105. Xing, Y. and Kolstad, C., D. Do Lax Environmental Regulations Attract Foreign Investment? Working Paper in Economics No. 6-95. University of California Santa Barbara. Department of Economics, 1997. Yohe, G. W. The Backward Incidence of Pollution Control - Some Comparative Staties irn General Equilibrium. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 6: 187- 198, 1979. Yu, E. S. H. and Ingene, C. A. The Backward Incidence of Pollution Control irn a Rigid-Wage Economy. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 9: 304-310, 1982. 253 APPENDIX CALCULATION ON OPTIMAL REGULATION-INCOME ELASTICITY Let utility U be defined as a function of material well-being (M), and healfin (H), according to fine following formula: (i) U = W " . The formula is an extended Cobb-Douglas formula, leaving fine total share of healfin and material well being constant. 5‘ The model is simplified compared to fine presentation inn ETERNA since it neglects finat healfin has an impact on production itself via labor productivity. Under non-restrictive assumptions, such incorporation will not influence fine basic proposition.” Furfinermore, material well being is a function of production (P) minus abatement expenditure (A): (ii) M = P — A. Finally, fine impact of abatement on healfin (H) follows fine functiorn (iii) H = %g) a. This means that healfin improves wifin an elasticity of or, if fine share of abatenernt expenditure in fine economy increases, but worsens proportionally, if production increases. Utility can finerefore be expressed as 254 (iv) U = (P - A)P"’" ’“’A"’. The abatement expenditures is optimally set at: (v) A: “'7 P. I+an Wifin fine chosen utility form, fine optimal adjustment pafin for a country as it gets richer would be to keep abatement expenditures at a constant ratio to overall income. This rate itself is higher, fine bigger fine extemality (i.e., fine higher or) is. A higher efl‘ectiveness of abatement expenditures (represented by a higher 11) has an analogous efl‘ect The formulation therefore would imply a unitary elasticity of pollution abatement expenditures with respect to income increases. This means finat fine regulatory elasticity of income would be zero. In other words, fine level of pollution per unit of output would remain constant Following equation (iii), pollution would increase as a result of growfin. The reason for finis lies in equation (i). In finis forrnulatiorn, bofin marginal costs and benefits increase in proportion to income, leaving fine benefit cost ratio unchanged. s"ItisonlynecessarytoassurnetlnatmaterialoutputfollowsaCobb-Douglasfnrnctiornoflaborand capital.Infiniscase,theoverallutilityfunctioncouldbepresentedinthcsamebasicformas U=W",exceptthatnnowincludesbothproductiveandhedoniccfl’ectsofexternality. 255