PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MTE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE _2 t.» no 39’ JAN 0 3200,17 1/98 c/Clmms-ou DETERMINANTS OF PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES IN FAST GROWING LOCAL GOVERNMENTS OF MICHIGAN By GETACHEW W. BEGASHAW A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1998 ABSTRACT DETERMINANTS OF PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES IN FAST GROWING LOCAL GOVERNMENTS OF MICHIGAN By Getachew W. Begashaw This study analyzes the factors that determine the variations in per capita public service expenditures of forty-six fast growing local governments in the State of Michigan. Fast growing local governments were defined as cities and townships that had 5,000 or more residents by 1990 and had grown by at least 1,000 persons between 1980 and 1990. All the seventeen cities and twenty-nine of the fifty-two townships that qualified as fast growing communities in the state were included in the study. Categories of public services considered in the study included general government, public safety, public works, public services, health and welfare, and recreation and culture. The study was based on US Census population figures of 1980 and 1990 and the 1994 population projection of the Michigan Department of Management; public service expenditures from the Comprehensive Annual Financial Report (1981 to 1995) of the local governments; state equalized value of properties (1981 to 1995) of the all the communities; public safety data of 1990 and 1905 for all cities and townships in the study; and roads and streets expenditure for selected communities. An expenditure decision model of local governments was developed assuming that the general objective of local governments is to provide the best possible public services (maximizing service benefits) with minimum expenditures. A rigorous method of data preparation for the purpose of such analysis was developed and a Fixed Eflects econometric model was employed to analyze the huge panel data sets. The empirical results showed that: in terms of 1995 constant dollars, per capita public service expenditures of fast growing communities in Michigan vary widely; cities and townships of different population sizes have different expenditure patterns (while cities with smaller population size spend more than cities with larger population size, townships with larger population size spend more than smaller townships); and communities located in Southeast Michigan spend more than those in the rest of the state. More importantly, while the explanatory power of all variables varied across community groups, the per capita state equalized value of total property was found to be a consistently significant variable in explaining the variations in expenditures of local governments. The more wealth, the more spending. The general policy implication derived from the empirical findings was that more people could be added to the existing smaller communities to decrease per capita expenditures. Ifsmall communities were to grow to achieve economies of scale in utilizing the existing service infrastructures, they need not contribute to sprawl since sprawl refers to low density development, not growth in population. If re—directing population growth into smaller size communities is to be actualized, the savings that could be obtained fi'om the joint impact of increased population and a dense new residential development could be substantial. I dedicate this dissertation to my children Noah and Gabrielua through whom I remember my past and in whom I find meaning for my life in the future. iv ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to convey my thanks and gratitude to all who have served in my thesis committee. First and foremost, my indebtedness goes to Prof. A Allan Schmid, my mentor, major professor, and thesis supervisor. His unflagging support and thoughtful guidance have been so much invaluable to me and were critical in my successful completion of my graduate studies, including writing this dissertation. I have immensely benefited from his insightful and scholarly discussion and comments to improve the quality and focus of my research. I also want to thank Prof. James F. Oehmke who has always been a source of motivation and guidance for me ever since I joined the department. His prompt response to many of the questions I had and the keen interest he had in my research have played vital role in shaping the focus and content my thesis. I am extremely grateful to Prof. Lynn R. Harvey, who not only served as a member of my thesis committee, but also provided me with the most needed data for my research. Many of his sharp comments have been valuable in refining the makeup of my dissertation and highlighting the germane policy issues that are of interest to local governments. I would also like to sincerely thank Dr. Raymond D. Vlasin for serving in my thesis committee and giving me several helpful suggestions that helped me to improve my dissertation in form and content. In addition, I wish to acknowledge that it was a privilege for me to have both Professors James T. Bonnen and Paul W. Strassmann for having served in my committee before their retirement. Well, I can never thank enough Dr. James E. Jay, Assistant to Vice-Provost of CANK for helping me out with financial assistance at the very critical time in my graduate program in the university. I am extremely thankful to him and the Office of Diversity and Pluralism for the financial help I received for three years as a Graduate Assistant. I also esteem the assistantships and fellowships given to me at different times by the Urban Afl'airs, Graduate School, the College of Agriculture and Natural Resources, and Department of Agricultural Economics. My sincere appreciation is also for all my graduate colleagues in the department that have made my stay in the university fi'uitful and pleasant. My special mention goes to Dr. Georges Dimithe, Dr. Berhanu G. Medhin, and Mr. Adnan Ozair, who have in one way or another contributed towards my success in writing this dissertation. I would like to mention my deepest gratitude to all clerks, treasurers, accountants, planners, and stafi‘ of all the forty-six local governments that are included in this study for firlly cooperating and providing me with all the data and information I used in this research. Finally, but most importantly, I would like to express my admiration and appreciation to my wife Senait G. Tsadik. During those difficult times, when I was struggling with my research, she raised our two little children, Noah and Gabrielua. Despite the precious time she sacrificed to help me finish my dissertation, she also managed to make time for a successful completion of her graduate studies with high honor. Indeed, I am blessed to have her as part of my life. TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ..................................................................................................... List of Figures .................................................................................................... CHAPTER 1. AN INTRODUCTION TO PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES ..................................................................... 1.1 Introduction ..................................................................................... 1.2 Background ..................................................................................... 1.3 Problem Statement ........................................................................... 1.4 Research Objectives ......................................................................... CHAPTER 2. LITERATURE REVIEW............ ........................................... 2.1 Introduction ..................................................................................... 2.2 Public Service Expenditure Studies .................................................. 2.3 Lessons From the Studies ................................................................. CHAPTER 3. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK TO ESTIMATE DETERMINANTS OF PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES ..................................................................... 3.1 Introduction ..................................................................................... 3.2 The Expenditures Model .................................................................. 3.3 The Dependent Variable ................................................................... 3.4 The Independent Variables ............................................................... 3.4.1 Population Size .................................................................. 3.4.2 Population Growth Rate .................................................... 3.4.3 Population Density ............................................................ 3.4.4 Property Value and Land Use Characteristics ..................... 3.5 Attributes of Services and Model Specification .................................. 3.6 Omitted Variables ............................................................................. 3.6.1 Inter-govemmental Revenue Transfers ............................... 3.6.2 Household Income ............................................................. 3.7 Unit of Observation and Categories of Analysis ................................. 3.7.1 Types of Government ......................................................... 3.7.2 Geographic Location .......................................................... 3.7.3 Population Size Groups ...................................................... vii Page x xiii l l 4 7 10 11 ll 11 39 44 44 44 45 45 46 48 48 49 50 51 51 52 53 54 55 56 56 CHAPTER 4. ANALYTICAL METHODS FOR ESTIMATING DETERMINANTS OF VARIATIONS IN PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES ..................................................... 4.1 Introduction ...................................................................................... 4.2 The Data ........................................................................................... 4.2.1 Population .......................................................................... 4.2.2 Expenditures ...................................................................... 4.2.2.1 General Fund ...................................................... 4.2.2.2 Special Funds ...................................................... 4.2.2.3 Debt Service Funds ............................................. 4.2.2.4 Capital Projects Funds ......................................... 4.2.3 Adjusting Expenditures ...................................................... 4.2.4 Excluded Fund Types ......................................................... 4.2.5 Netting Out Expenditures ................................................... 4.2.6 Inflation Adjustment ........................................................... 4.2.7 Amortization ...................................................................... 4.2.8 State Equalized Value of Properties ................................... 4.2.9 Population Density ............................................................ 4.3 The Empirical Method of Analysis .................................................... 4.3.1 The Fixed Efl‘ects Econometric Model ................................ 4.3.2 Assumptions of the Fixed Effects Regression ...................... 4.3.2.1 Heterogeneity of Units of Observations ................ 4.3.2.2. Stochastic Relationship.................................. 4.3.2.3 The Residuals ..................................................... 4.3.3 Mathematical Representation of the Fixed Effects Model ......................................................... CHAPTER 5. DETERMINANTS OF PER CAPITA PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES IN FAST GROWING COMMUNITIES OF MICHIGAN ......................................................................... 5.1 Introduction ..................................................................................... 5.2 The Variables ................................................................................... 5.2.1 Population .......................................................................... 5.2.2 Equalized Value of Properties ............................................ 5.2.3 Total Land Area and Population Density ............................. 5.2.4 Per Capita Public Service Expenditures ............................... 5.3 Data Classification ............................................................................ 5.3.1 Classification by Types of Government ............................... 5.3.2 Sub-Classification by Population Size and Geographic Location .................................................. viii 57 57 57 58 62 64 66 66 67 67 68 70 71 74 78 80 82 83 84 84 84 85 86 88 88 88 89 92 97 98 102 102 105 5.4 Characteristics of the Study Communities by Sub-Classification ....................................................................... 106 5.4.1 Cities .................................................................................. 106 5.4.1.1 Cities of Larger Population Size ........................... 106 5.4.1.2 Cities of Smaller Population Size .......................... 107 5.4.1.3 Cities in Southeast Michigan ................................ 107 5.4.1.4 Cities in the Rest of the State ............................... 108 5.4.2 Townships .......................................................................... 108 5.4.2.1 Townships of Larger Population Size ................... 109 5.4.2.2 Townships of Smaller Population Size .................. 109 5.4.2.3 Townships in Southeast Michigan ........................ 110 5.4.2.4 Townships in the Rest of the State ....................... 110 5.5 Regressions and Model Specifications ............................................... 112 5.5.1 Diagnostic Regressions ....................................................... 112 5.5.1.1 Results of Diagnostic Regressions ........................ 113 5.5.1.2 Results of Diagnostic Regressions - Cities ............ 115 5.5.1.3 Results of Diagnostic Regressions - Townships 118 5.5.2 Fixed Effects Regressions .................................................... 120 5.5.2.1 Regression Results ............................................... 121 5.5.2.2 Regression Results for Cities ............................... 121 5.5.2.3 Regression Results for Townships ....................... 130 5.6 Comparison of Regression Results by Types of Government ............. 135 5.7 Impact of Location on Expenditures ................................................... 137 5.8 Reliability Test of the Model ............................................................. 138 CHAPTER 6. CONCLUSIONS, IMPLICATIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH .............................................................................. 141 6.1 Introduction ...................................................................................... 141 6.2 Conclusions ....................................................................................... 142 6.3 Policy Implications ............................................................................ 152 6.4 Future Research ................................................................................ 155 BIBLIOGRAPHY .............................................................................................. 158 APPENDICES .................................................................................................... 163 163 Appendix A: Summary Statistics ....................................................................... 169 Appendix B: Correlation Analysis of the Variables ........................................... 170 Appendix C: Diagnostic Regression Results ...................................................... 178 Appendix D: Fixed Effects Regression ............................................................. 188 Appendix E: General Linear Model Regressions ................................................ 190 Appendix F: Fixed Efl‘ects Regression With Location Variable .......................... 191 Appendix G: Sample Regression Data ................................................................. ix Table 2.1 Table 4.1: Table 4.2: Table 4.3: Table 4.4: Table 4.5 Table 4.6: Table 4.7: Table 4.8 Table 4.9 Table 4.10 Table 4.11: Table 4.12: LIST OF TABLES Summary of Selected Studies on Public Service Expenditures .................................................... All Fast Growing Cities in Michigan ....................................... All Fast Growing Townships in Michigan .............................. Townships Selected for the Study ........................................... Combined Statement of Revenues and Expenditures, Meridian Township, 1994 ....................................................... Deflators of Operating and Capital Project Expenditures .......................................................................... Unadjusted Public Service Expenditures of Meridian Township ............................................................................... Adjusted and Amortized Total Expenditures of Meridian Township ............................................................................... Amortized and Nominal Capital Project Expenditures of Meridian Township ................................................................. Amortized and Adjusted Capital Project Expenditures of Meridian Township ................................................................. Per Capita Public Service Expenditures of Meridian Township ................................................................. State Equalized Value of Properties, Meridian Township ............................................................................... Total Land Area and Population Density of Meridian Township ................................................................. Page 14 59 60 61 65 72 73 75 76 77 78 79 80 Table 4.13: Table 5.1: Table 5.2: Table 5.3: Table 5.4 (a): Table 5.4 (b): Table 5.4 (c): Table 5.4 (d): Table 5.5(a): Table 5.5(b): Table 5.6: Table 5.7: Table 5.8: Table 5.9: Table 5.10: Table 5.11: Total Land Area of the Fast Growing Local Governments in the State of Michigan ................................ Mean, Minimum, and Maximum Values of Selected Variables .............................................................. Average Total Population of the Fast Growing Cities in Michigan ........................................................................ Average Total Population of the Sampled Fast Growing Townships in Michigan ........................................ Average PCSEV of Business Properties, Cities ................................................................................. Average PCSEV of Residential Properties, Cities ................................................................................. Average PCSEV of Business Properties, Townships ......................................................................... Average PCSEV of Residential Properties, Townships ..................................................................... Townships with Average Population Density of 1,000 or More ............................................................... Cities with Average Population Density of 1,000 or More ............................................................... Average Expenditures and Population, Cities ..................... Average Expenditures and Population, Townships ............. Single Factor ANOVA, by Types of Government, .............. Single Factor ANOVA, by Geographic Location of Local Governments ............................................................ Summary of Basic Characteristics of Fast Growing Cities in Michigan .............................................................. Summary of Basic Characteristics of Fast Growing Townships in Michigan ..................................................... 81 89 90 91 94 94 95 96 97 98 100 101 104 105 108 111 Table S.12(a): Results of the Diagnostic Regressions , Cities and Townships ...................................................................... 115 Table 5.12(b): The t-statistics of the Diagnostic Regressions, Cities and Townships .............................................................. 115 Table 5.13(a): Results of the Diagnostic Regressions, Cities ......................... 117 Table 5.13(b): The t-statistics of the Diagnostic Regressions, Cities ............ 117 Table 5.14(a): Results of the Diagnostic Regressions, Townships ................ 1 18 Table 5. 14(b): The t-statistics Results of Diagnostic Regressions, Townships ............................................................................. 1 19 Table 5.15: Fixed Efl‘ects Regression Results, Cities ................................ 122 Table 5.16: Ranking of the Independent Variables by the Level of Significance, Cities ................................................... 129 Table 5.17: Fixed Effects Regression Results, Township ......................... 131 Table 5.18: Ranking of the Independent Variables by the Level of Significance, Townships ........................................... 134 Table 5.19: Comparison of the Ranking of Independent Variables by Types of Government ........................................ 136 Table 5.20 Results of the Reliability Test, Cities ..................................... 139 Table 5.21 Results of the Reliability Test, Townships ............................ 140 xii LIST OF FIGURES Page Figure 5.1 Average Population and Expenditures, all Cities ................................................................................ 124 Figure 5.2 Average Population and Expenditures Cities Outside of Southeast Michigan .................................... 124 Figure 5.3 Average Population and Expenditures of Cities in Southeast Michigan ................................................ 125 Figure 5.4 Average Population and Expenditures, Large Crtres .......................................................................... 125 Figure 5.5 Average Population and Expenditures of 126 ‘ Cities with Smaller Population size ..................................... Figure 5.6 Average Population and Expenditures of 132 . all Townships ........................................................................ Figure 5.7 Average Population and Expenditures of 132 Townships in Southeast Michigan ..................................... Figure 5.8 Average Population and Expenditures of 133 Townships Outside of Southeast Michigan ........................ Figure 5.9 Average Population and Expenditures of 133 Townships with Large Population Size ............................... Figure 5.10 Average Population and Expenditures of 134 Townships with Small Population Size .............................. xiii CHAPTER ONE AN INTRODUCTION TO PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES 1.1 Introduction "T wo factors of practical efliciency may be applied to the government of a city: What does it provide for the people, and what does it cost the people? " (James Bryce, 1914) As municipal corporations, authorized by their respective charters, local governments in Michigan provide basic public services like police protection, fire control, roads, water and sewer, parks and recreation, public improvements, planning and zoning, and general administrative services to the residents in their jurisdictions. These services have associated costs that are commonly referred to as public service expenditures. The services provided and expenditures incurred are, more or less, similar for most local governments in Michigan. They are paid for by the residents in form of taxes, charges, assessments, and state transfers. Yet, there are significant variations in the amount and range of the per capita public service expenditures across most communities in Michigan, ranging fi'om $34 to $1,029 in constant 1995 dollars. From where do these variations or difi‘erences in expenditures come? Although each local government in Michigan gets a sizable amount of dollars fi'om the state revenue sharing, they finance most of the public services they provide through the revenues they generate locally. The public service revenue sources include taxes on properties, businesses, and income. These revenue sources largely depend on how communities use their lands. For instance, communities characterized by agricultural or residential properties will be quite different from communities characterized by industrial or commercial developments in their revenue generating ability. All communities do not have equal number of residents (or population) and they do not necessarily grow at equal rate. Public services are neither exclusionary nor rival in their consumption. But, there are limits to how much services could be provided to a growing number of people without reducing the quality of life (or services) and incurring additional costs to the existing residents. On average, there is a threshold of population size to a given level of public service beyond which the marginal cost of providing the services could rise immensely. There are several ways in which residents of adjoining communities could create costs to communities in which they do not live or pay for the costs they create. Roads, police and fire, public libraries and parks are few such services fi'om which outsiders can not be excluded. Then, is it settlement congestion, as measured by location of communities, or population size, grth rate, and density that drive expenditures of communities? Or, it is the land use or development patterns of each local government that is the sources of variations in expenditures of communities in Michigan? Inquiry into this topic is not new; it has been around since the early 1900. Several studies have been conducted; but, no consensus has evolved. The current study attempts to contribute its share in clarifying the factors that drive public service expenditures of local governments by: (1) developing a rigorous method of organizing and using relevant data sets, and (2) enriching the method of analysis by employing the Fixed Eflects Regression analysis of the extensive time-series cross-section (panel) data of Michigan. The chapters are organized as follows: problem statement and research objectives including this section of introduction are presented in Chapter One. Chapter Two contains the literature review in which several major works in the topic are reviewed and the lessons fi'om the studies are highlighted. Chapter Three develops the conceptual fi'amework of the research and explains the model, the variables, and the classes of analysis. Chapter Four discusses the analytical methods of the study and explains the methods of adjusting and organizing the data, the econometric model chosen, and the mathematical representation of the regression equation. Chapter Five presents the empirical results and discussion of the analysis and the reliability test of the model. Finally, Chapter Six summarizes the findings obtained from the study, policy implications for local governments, and future research needs. 1.2 Background Michigan, with a population of 9.5 million and a job base of 4.9 million in 1995, has 83 counties and about 2,100 local governments. Nearly 50 percent of the population and employment are located in the Southeast Michigan region, which comprises only seven counties; Livingston, Macomb, Monroe, Oakland, St. Clair , Washtenaw, and Wayne. It is projected that the population of Michigan will grow by 1.1 million people and 670,000 new jobs between 1995 and 2020. According to this projection, 38 and 44 percents of the new population and jobs respectively will be in Southeast Michigan (MSPO: 1995; Burchell: 1997). The Michigan Society of Planning Officials reported that if the current pattern of development continues, the state will incur significant costs for new infrastructure as well as the costs of urban decline. It further notes that this pattern of development is not inevitable and an informed public could achieve different fixture through coordinated and integrated land-use planning and have a dramatic effect on the public and private resources consumed for land development (MSPO: 1995). Thus, among many critical settlement issues that need further research and knowledge are where and how to settle the increased population to save on resources consumed and the associated public service expenditures (Burchell: 1997; Schmid: 1997). Observing that many of the cities in the US have increased their public service expenditures by more than 40 percent between 1951 and 1954 alone, Harvey E. Brazer suggested that this rapid increase in expenditures by American cities emphasizes the importance of extending our knowledge into the study of the relationship between public service expenditures and the factors that influence such expenditures (Brazer: 1959). Michigan provides an excellent environment to study the factors that influence increases and variations in public service expenditures, because it is one of the states that have the highest per capita public service expenditures in the nation. Citizens Research Council of Michigan (CRC) reported that in 1972/73 Michigan had a relatively higher per capita expenditures (combined per capita expenditures for state and local governments) in comparison with the national average and with those of the eight competitor states; Indiana, Ohio, Wisconsin, New York, Illinois, Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and Michigan. Michigan, with an average of $809.00 per capita public service expenditures, was the second highest alter New York in 1972. That same year, its exceeded the national average per capita by $97.00 (CRC, 1975). The general fill‘ld expenditures in Michigan increased by 66 percent (from $1.55 billion to $2.57 billion) between 1970 and 1974. The average annual increase was about 13.5 percent. Similarly, total expenditures fi'om all operating funds increased by 58.2 percent (from $3.13 billion to $5.37 Billion) during the‘same period. These increases in expenditures had given rise to increases in the general tax levels, including 10 percent increase in the state and local personal income tax combined (CRC, 1975). Similarly, the US Bureau of Census for fiscal 1987/88 reported that the state and local governments in Michigan had both relatively high revenues and expenditures compared with the national average and the average of the fifteen states with populations of over five million people. The fifteen most populous states are California, New York, Texas, Florida, Pennsylvania, Illinois, Ohio, Michigan, New Jersey, North Carolina, Virginia, Massachusetts, Indiana, and Missouri. During this fiscal year, state and local expenditures in Michigan were the fifth highest per capita and second highest per $1,000.00 personal income. The per capita expenditures were 7 percent higher than the average of the fifteen states and 9 percent higher than the national average (CRC, 1990). In contrast to this steady increase in per capita public service expenditures in Michigan, the per capita personal income rose by only 11 percent in real terms from 1979 to 1988. During this period, the fifteen states had a remarkable average of 23 percent increase in personal income and the national average was 21 percent (CRC, 1990). But, Michigan ranked fifih among the fifteen states in collecting more revenue, especially revenue fiom property and personal income taxes. The average per capita revenue for Michigan, the fifteen states, and the US were $3,107, $3,005, and $2,958 respectively (US Bureau of the Census, Government Finances in 1987/1988). 1.3 Problem Statement Recently, the Southeast Michigan Council of Governments (SEMCOG) had commissioned two studies relating to the costs of alternative settlement patterns in Michigan. The first was a study on Fiscal Impacts of Alternative Land Development Patterns in Michigan by Robert Burchell of Rutgers University. The other was a study on Impact of Population Growth and Distribution on Local Government Expenditures in Michigan by Allan Schmid of Michigan State University. The Burchell study focused on the resource consumption and public service costs of two alternative patterns of settlement, namely current trend (i.e. sprawl) and contained developments (i.e. dense). The study was a micro density study that compared the costs of infrastructure, housing, land, and public services at each selected study community level under the two scenarios and informed which one of the two will save resources and costs. This study, while very useful for the purpose of micro-settlement management, did not explain what the underlying factors other than settlement density were responsible for the steady increase in and variations of public service expenditures across communities in Michigan. The Schmid study was a macro-density approach focusing on the impact of population size and location of the community in relation to metropolitan area and investigated their impacts on public service expenditures. By employing a cross-sectional regression analysis for 1990 and 1995, it determined the most important explanatory variables that shaped the variations in public service expenditures. Generally, population grth could be expected to increase the tax base and revenue sources of a community (Oakland & Testa: 1995). On the other hand, as population increase reaches a certain threshold, demands for more and improved public services increase. This increase in demand, in turn, will place more pressure on local government budget and public service expenditures. Most of the public services (public safety, water and sewer, and roads for example) are congestablc goods with capacity constraints. Thse classes of goods may be having scale economies over a certain range of population and have a zero marginal cost as the number of users increases from zero to some given number. As congestion sets in, the addition of more users reduces the utility of services of all users and the marginal cost of additional users begins to rise sharply as an absolute capacity constraint is reached (Randall: 1987). It is a conventional wisdom that local governments need to invest more on public services in order to keep the quality and quantity of services fiom declining as a result population growth and congestion. However, many of the earlier studies have indicated that population growth and congestion are just few of the many other factors that explain the forces that drive public service expenditures of communities. Most of these studies were based on the use of a single year cross-sectional data. A cross-section analysis may be important not only for understanding of the underlying factors of local government expenditures as they are, but also for what it may hint about the possible future changes. However, as will be explained more in the literature review section, these studies were not able to create consensus on which variables are the most significant factors in shaping public service expenditures. It is this lack of uniformity in the findings of the difl‘erent studies that motivated the current study that employs difi‘erent approach and methods of studying the topic. Accordingly, the two strategic research questions that guide this study were: (1) what are the determinants or the significant factors that explain the variations in public service expenditures across communities in Michigan?; and (2) what are the policy implications of the findings for fixture population settlement and growth strategies for local governments Michigan? 10 1.4 Research Objectives This study attempts to identify the significant factors (determinants) that are behind the variations in per capita public service expenditures of fast growing communities (local goverrunents) in the State of Michigan. The analysis seeks to underscore how the association between per capita expenditures of the selected study communities and the explanatory variables will be affected by population size groups, types of government (city or township), and location (Southeast Michigan or rest of state). More specifically, the study attempts: (a) to establish a method of collecting, adjusting, and using local and state governments expenditures data to conduct a study of public service expenditures for different communities of Michigan; (b) to establish a method of comparing public service expenditures of different communities in Michigan; (c) to determine if there are significant difi‘erences in public service expenditures across communities in Michigan by population size, types of government, and geographic location; (d) to determine the significance of selected variables in influencing the variations in public service expenditures across fast growing communities in Michigan; and (e) to discuss the policy implications of the findings for future population settlement policies and grth strategies in Michigan. CHAPTER TWO LITERATURE REVIEW OF STUDIES ON PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES 2.1 Introduction The first section of this chapter reviews some of the major public service expenditure studies conducted so far. It focuses on the economic variables considered frequently and itemizes the important findings of the studies. It also describes the types of data used and methods of analysis applied in detail. The objectives, variables, and research outcomes of the studies are also presented in a form of summary (Table 2.1). The second section presents a brief summary and critique of the studies and points out how the current study will be different from them in the methods and approaches it used. This form of presenting the review was selected with the aim of providing better opportunity to identify and incorporate the most important economic variables frequently used by prior researchers into the current empirical model and analysis. 2.2 Public Service Expenditures Studies Although costs of governments had been interest of research for long time, the importance of more focused research on this vital area of concern, especially on the factors influencing public service expenditures, was spurred by the rapid increase in public 11 12 service expenditures of state and local governments in the US after the World War H (Brazer, 1959; Schmandt and Stephens, 1963). As the US was leaving the war period, the surpluses accumulated by state and local governments had to be used and some capital outlay and maintenance, deferred during the war, were resumed. Thus, interest in inquiring into the budgets and expenditures of state and local governments to determine if expenditures were extravagant or efiicient, taxes were too high or low, and whether borrowing was for planned developments or for benefit of interest groups grew (Berolzheimer, 1947). As a result, mainly in 1950s and 19605, several major studies and number of specialized articles on various aspects of local government finance appeared in professional literature. For example, Josef Berolzheimer wrote on “Influences Shaping Expenditure and Economic Structure in the United State” in 1952; Amos H. Hawley published an article on “Metropolitan Population and Municipal Government Expenditures in Central Cities” in 1952; Solomon Fabricant published his book titled The Trend of Government Activity in the United State Since 1900 in 1952; Scott and Feder examined the relationship between municipal expenditures and some selected variables for 192 cities in California in 1957; Brazer presented his study on City Expenditures in the United States in 1959; Johannes Delphendahl of Michigan State University wrote his doctoral dissertation on Expenditure Patterns and Services Rendered by Michigan Townships in 1961; Schmandt and Stephens contributed the article on “Local Government Expenditure Patterns in the United States’ in 1963; Woo Sik Kee wrote his doctoral dissertation on Metropolitan Area Finance Studies in 1964 and published an article on “Central City Expenditures” in 1965. 13 Public service expenditures are all public resources expended by state or local governments to produce certain public goods and services (such as police protection, fire control, public education, public health, roads, water and sewer systems. park and recreation, etc.) to improve the welfare and quality of life of the residents of that political jurisdiction. The focus of the researchers including those mentioned in the following table were the factors that derive or influence the public resources expended to provide these services. Different researchers had submitted different answers, and some others have supported each others findings. Berolzheimer (1947) analyzed the expenditure of operation of states and local governments in the US using the data reported by the Bureau of Census for the fiscal year 1942. The cities were divided into ten population size groups and a correlation analysis was done on the assumption that the independent variables that affect state and local expenditures were population size and density, income payments, and the volume of government functions. On the expenditures side, it was only the expenditure for operations that was considered. The operation expenditure, according to the author, was one significant part of expenditures and was sufficient, by itself, to provide tentative explanation relating to the association between state and local expenditures and the independent variables. That was because operation expenditure comprised all public pay rolls, current materials, current maintenance, public assistance payments, and other operations, representing most of the annually recurring costs of government. l4 Table 2.1 Summary of Selected Studies on Public Service Expenditures Study Objectives Variables Findings Berolzheimer( (1) To explore the Dependent variable: the cost (1) City expenditures were 1947) factors shaping state [expenditures] of public correlated with population and local operation operations size, (2)excepting for expenditures, (2) to counties with population identify systematic Independent variables: total less than 10,000, county ways of classifying and population, population density, expenditures did not vary comparing public income payments, volume of markedly with population finances functions. size Hawley, 1951 Testing the Dependent variable: per capita (l) The per capita interdependence of all government expenditures, government expenditures operating expenditures, and were more closely related populauons lying capital improvement to population residing within and without the expenditures. outside the city than to b0 1 'es of local population within the city, Independent variables: and governments involving . population size, density, and (2) operating were the use of the more related to population . . growth rate, number m labor residing mumcrpal government force, number in white collar outside the city than expenditures occupation, number of houses, population within the city houses per square mile, area in square miles, percent of population incorporated, and percent of total district population. Table 2.1 (Cont’d) 15 Study Objectives Variables Findings Brazer, (l) establishing Dependent variable: total (1) population density and 1959 ms of differences operation and functional intergovernmental revenue category expenditures per per capita were the most m per capita capita significant variables in expenditures of cities, explaining all categories of (2) analyzing the Independent variables: expenditures. iation between population size, population (2) population m and population growth rate were city expenditures per densrty, pop ulatron growth of least importance in capi ta and l 1e rate, median farmly income, shaping crty expenditures, economic variables percentage of population and (3) median family income employed, and was significant in explaining intergovernmental revenue. variations in functional categories only. Schmandt and (1) give an overview of Dependent variable: mean (1) state aids and median Stephens, 1963 local goverrunent per capita expenditures of family income were the most expenditure patterns by total and functional important variables geographic regions, categories influencing per capita and spending by county area (2) indicate the factors Independent variables: total aggregate, and that influence local population, population (2) total population and ndin levels densrty, terntorral area state density did not afiect total spe g aids, median family income per capita expenditures appreciably Table 2.1 (Cont’d) l6 Study Objectives Variables Findings Woo Sik Kee, (1) Discuss critical Dependent variables: Determinants of each of the 1965 differences of socio- (1) total general expenditures, dependent variables by economic and (2) non-educational ranking were: governmental expenditures. and (l) for total general characteristics (3) non-aided expenditures expenditures: state aid, ratio between the city and of central city population to areas outside the Independent variables: its SMSA population. per central city. (1) per capita income, capita income, ratio of state (2) Show the (2) owner-occupied housing and local expenditure relationships between units as percent of total responsibility, and owner- occupied units, occupied housing units as the level or per capita (3) population density, percent of total occupied city expenditures and (4) ratio of central city units; selected explanatory population to total SMSA (2) for per capita non- variables population, (5).ratio of state educational expenditure: state and local functional responsibility, and (6) per capita state aid aid, owner-occupied housing units as percent of total occupied units, ratio of central city population to its SMSA population, and ratio of state and local expenditure responsibility; and non-aided expenditure. Table 2.1 (Cont’d) l7 Study Objectives Variables Findings Masten and Explain that the Dependent variable: total city (1) The coefficient of multiple Quindry, relative importance of per capita current general determination (R’) was low for 1970 the popular expenditure purpose expenditures cities ranging from 5,000 to factors, other than 20,000 and high for cities with population and Independent variables: population of 20,000 to intergovernmental population, population density, 100’000’ transfers, can be most (2) The contributions of the meaningfully assessed per cap ita adjusted gross independent variables to the only for areas of income, per capita full value of coefficient of multiple relatively homogenous assessed property, and land determination vary by city population sizes. sizes. area. Schmid, (1) Investigate if public Dependent variable: total (1) expenditures and 1997 service expenditures expenditures per capita. population size matters for could be reduced by townships; altering macro-patterns Independent variables: total (2) location mattersfor cities; of future settlement (or population, population growth and development). rate, location, total state (3) cities in southeast (2) Determine if growth equalized value of property, Michigan had higher total location and population and percent of state equalized expenditures per capita than size have effect on value of residential property cities in the rest of the state public service while townships did not show expenditures. such difi'erence 18 The correlation analysis revealed that city expenditures were highly correlated with population size. Per capita city expenditures ranged from $72.69 (in cities with populations over one million) to $11.22 (in cities with populations less than 2,500). The direction of changes in population size and expenditures followed the same direction without any exception; i.e., expenditures increase when population sizes increase and expenditures decrease when population sizes decrease. In contrast to the variation in city expenditures in relation to population, the per capita county expenditures did not vary significantly among population size groups excepting for the smallest group. While all of the four county population size groups (over 250,000; 50,000 - 250,000; 25,000 - 50,000; 10,000 - 25,000; and under 10,000) had per capita county expenditures within the range of $12.38 to $13.76, the smallest counties with populations less than 10,000 had per capita expenditure of $22.72 showing diseconomies of scale. Amos H. Hawley’s 1952 study was based on two major assumptions. (1) City services which were bought with municipal government expenditures were developed to meet the total need generated by activity carried on within the city. (2) Some of those activities, and hence some of the need for city services, arose from the population residing outside the city boundaries. According to Hawley, the outlying population uses the city streets and public buildings; it creates more police problems, thus affecting the expenditure of that service; it causes additional fire risks which must be factored in allocation of firnds for fire protection; and its movement in and out of the city is a factor in the budget of the health department of the city. Then, the hypothesis arising fiom these assumptions was that the annual expenditures of city governments should vary with the sizes of populations l9 occupying adjoining areas. A corollary hypothesis of these assumptions was that the larger the proportion of the total population living outside the city, the heavier should be the tax burden on the population living within the city. Hawley used the 1940 Bureau of Census data for seventy six cities with population over 100,000 to perform correlation analysis. The correlation between all per capita expenditures of city government and city population was found to be was slightly curvilinear ( y = 0.51). However, he believed that the curvilinearity may be due to lack of control of related variables and assumed, but not tested, that multiple correlation analysis could correct the problem. The zero-order correlation coefficient was computed for each of the three dependent variables (namely, all government expenditures, operating expenditures, and capital improvement expenditures) with the eight demographic variables of the city governments and the remainder of the districts (population size, population density, population grth rate, number in labor force, number in white collar occupation, number of houses, houses per square mile, area in square miles, percent of population incorporated, and percent of total district population). The per capita expenditures of the governments (computed on the population residing within the city) were more closely related to population living outside the city than to the population residing within the city. The per capita operating costs also revealed similar result. Based on this general observation, the major hypothesis that stated the annual expenditures of city governments should vary with the sizes of populations occupying adjoining areas appeared to hold. However, the study showed that the capital improvement expenditures were only 20 slightly associated with the independent variables reflecting, according to the author, the inadequacy of a single year data for a study of capital improvement expenditures. The operating expenditures were more sensitive to variations in population than were capital improvement expenditures. Likewise, government expenditures were more closely associated with density of population within the city (r = 0.53) than with the size of city population (r = 0.40) The correlation between population growth rate and the dependent variables was found to be slight and inverse in Hawley’s study. The cities and their surrounding districts also showed no appreciable differences in this respect. Similarly, the association between the labor force and government expenditures was insignificant for both the cities and the remainder of the districts. However, the result became highly correlated when it was for the number of people employed in white collar occupations and government expenditures. Housing density was also found to be more consistently related to government expenditures than the number of houses in the city or the total area of the city in square miles. Taking note of the major finding of his study, Hawley focused more on the correlation of population and the dependent variables and asked to what extent the association between expenditures and population was influenced by variations in other independent variables. Then, multiple correlation (R) for government expenditures and population was computed by successively adding each of the other variables specified for the cities and the remainder of the districts. Of all the variables, the density of population within the cities was found to exert significant influence on the association of all expenditures and population size; the measure of the population and government 21 expenditures changed from r = 0.40 to R = 0.55. The influence of the rest of the variables was found to be not significant. The extent to which all the independent variables (8 for cities and 10 for the surrounding metropolitan districts) explain the variations in all city government expenditures was computed and R2 of 0.57 was obtained . That is, the total effect of all the independent variables accounted for only 57 percent of the variation in all municipal expenditures in the cities. The R2 for operating expenditures and capital improvement expenditures were found to be 0.59 and 0.54 respectively Forty percent of the variation in city government expenditures remain unexplained. The existence of such large residue, according to Hawley, may have been due to inadequate definitions of jurisdictional areas (like metropolitan districts) employed by the Bureau of Census or missing important variables in the model. For instance, consideration of per capita income may be important in that it reflects the ability and willingness of the population to support the city governments expenditures. Similarly, the nature of the local economy could be important in that the economic characteristics of the surrounding cities have significant impact on the budget and expenditures ofthe city under consideration. With the main objectives of establishing patterns of differences in per capita expenditures of cities and analyzing the association between city expenditures per capita and important economic variables, Harvey E. Brazer studied per capita expenditures of 462 US large cities in 1951 and per capita expenditures of the 40 largest of these cities in 1953. The expenditure categories included were total general operating and six firnctional categories (police, fire, highways, recreation, general control, and sanitation). Capital outlays, largely reflecting construction programs, were excluded from the study because 22 the author considered this category of expenditure to vary from year to year. Yet, the capital expenditures of police, fire, and general control were not netted out because the Census Bureau data used for the study did not provide a breakdown between capital and current expenditures of these functional categories by individual cities. Measures of variations of expenditures per capita, as computed from the data of Bureau of the Census, Compendium of City Government Finances (1950), for all the 462 cities indicated that the variation coefficient for total general operating was 54.3 and 22.8 for common firnctions'. These variations coefficients reflected the difl‘erences among cities in the distribution of firnctional responsibilities. The mean, lowest, and highest total general operating expenditures for all the 462 cities were $47.57, $12.86, and $165.16 respectively; and $28.26, $11.31, and $80.66 for common firnctions. The data, when evaluated by geographic divisional means, showed that there was a variation in the per capita total general operating expenditure ranging fi'om $28.28 for cities of the West North Central states to 89.19 for cities in the New England states. The highest per capita expenditures were found to be in the older cities of New England, Middle Atlantic, and South Atlantic states, where, the author believed, traditions of local autonomy in government were strongest and their cities had retained responsibilities for most of the optional functions of city governments. Most of these firnctions were administered by the state, school district, or county elsewhere in the nation. In contrast, the per capita total general operation expenditure was the lowest for newer cities of West North Central and West South Central states, where cities generally enjoy fewer measures of political and economic importance. 23 Taking California, Ohio, and Massachusetts as states for regional comparison, Brazer found that the variation coefficients of the total general operating expenditure for cities in these states were very different fiom that of the 462 cities considered together. They were 23.5 for 35 cities in California, 8.8 for 30 cities in Ohio, and 25.0 for 32 cities in Massachusetts compared to 54.3 for all the 462 cities across the nation. The between states and within states variance of the total general operating per capita expenditure category were 6,097.58 and 215.48 respectively with F value of 28.3, while those for the common firnctions category were 468.40 and 47.28 with 9.9 F value. The correlation analysis of the association between expenditure categories revealed that only two sets of functional categories (police protection and fire control and police protection and general control) had a correlation coefficient greater than 0.5. Ifall functional categories were shaped or influenced by same explanatory variable(s), the author explained, high coefiicient of correlation would have been obtained among all categories. Moreover, the budgetary patterns among cities were extremely diverse suggesting that no single factor accounted for the variation among cities in per capita expenditures. Therefore, there was no compelling evidence to expect cities within individual states to follow a consistent pattern than in the case of the 462 cities taken together. The least-square multiple regression analysis was used to describe the average relationship between the per capita expenditure and the selected independent variables. The cities were divided into five sub-groups: the 462 cities with population greater than 25,000 in 1950 (because complete data for that year was available for places with 1 Common function category included were police, fire, highways, recreation, general control, and sanitation. 24 population of 25,000 or more sizes); 35 cities in California; 32 cities in Ohio; 30 in cities in Massachusetts (the three states were selected as three sub-groups for the purpose of holding the factors peculiar to individual states constant); and 40 cities, excluding Washington DC, with population greater than 250,000 in 1950 (because they form homogeneous group in terms of population and expenditure data for their overlying units of governments were available. These data were required to compute the ratio of the city’s population to that of its metropolitan area). The basic assumption of the analysis was that all of the relationships among the variables were linear and the sum of the squared deviations of the estimated values were reduced to their least possible magnitude. The regression results were presented in terms of estimated coefficients ([3), elasticities, and multiple correlation coefficients. The estimated coefficients were the weight assigned to a particular independent variable. The elasticities were the measure of percent change in the dependent variable induced by 1 percent change in the specified independent variable. The multiple correlation coeficients measure the degree of association between the dependent and independent variables. The coefficients of multiple correlation of the regression analysis range fi'om 0.76 for total general operating to 0.24 for firnctional category of recreation. That means, the highest ability of the model to explain the factors behind expenditures was 58 percent at its best and 6 percent at its lowest. However, some instructive generalization had emerged from the exercise. With a due caution of census data error, the analysis had shown that the association between population size and almost all, but police, per capita expenditures was not statistically significant as measured by its [3 value and elasticity measure (.015). 25 In a sharp contrast to the role of population size in explaining expenditure variations for the 462 cities, population density had shown a remarkable association with all types of expenditures with the exception of recreation. Excepting for its minor association with total operation and fire protection expenditures, population grth did not appear to have role in shaping municipal expenditures. The median family income, excepting for total general operating expenditure, had statistically significant positive association with all expenditures of firnctional categories. Ratio of employment had a sort of mixed results. The association between employment in manufacturing, trade, and service sectors and per capita expenditures appeared to increase as population increased. But the regression coefficients relating this variable with most of the expenditures were not compelling. Of all the six independent variables in the regression model, it was only the intergovernmental revenue per capita that was significant in explaining all expenditure categories. The research conducted by Schmandt and Stephens (1963) was national in scope, covering all the 3,096 counties in the nation. Using the 1957 Census of Government data, it employed county area aggregates (in which expenditures by all local goverrunents and special and school districts were grouped together) as unit of analysis. The 3,096 counties were sub-divided into the traditional nine regions classification of the Bureau of Census (New England, Middle Atlantic, East north Central, West North Central, South Atlantic, East South Central, West South Central, Mountain, and Pacific). Like in Hawley’s (1952), zero order correlation analysis was used to determine the relationship of the mean per capita expenditures of county area aggregates and the independent variables. The independent variables were total population, population 26 density, territorial area, state aids, and median family income. The total expenditures were composed of two expenditure categories: total current expenditures and capital expenditures. The functional categories included in the study were highways, public education, police, fire, parks and recreation, general control, sewerage and sanitation, and health and welfare. The descriptive statistics of the data showed wide differences in the regional aggregate per capita total expenditures ranging fi'om an average low of $80.56 (for the East South Central States of Alabama, Kentucky, Mississippi, and Tennessee) to average high of $221.06 (for the Pacific region including California, Oregon, and Washington). In general, the Southern states were at the low end of all the per capita expenditures and the western states were toping the list, followed by the Middle Atlantic States of New York, New Jersey, and Pennsylvania. The ranking by functional categories also followed the same pattern. The computation of the expenditures data for counties in all regions, excepting the East South Central, indicated that those counties with population less than 5,000 had the highest operating expenditures of all population size categories. However, the authors cautioned that care must be taken in making a generalized assumption of systematic relationship between per capita expenditures and population size because of the existence of considerable variations within size groups as well as between them. In addition, the data used in this particular study suggested that both the very large and very small counties suffer fiom diseconomies of scale yielding the usual “U” shaped curve on the population- per capita expenditures space. 27 The population per capita expenditure scenario appeared to be a little different when the capital improvement expenditure was considered separately. Although the counties with population under 5,000 spent more than the subsequent four population size categories of higher order, the difference was very small. The steeper upswing started with the population size category of 50,000 - 100,000 and the per capita expenditures of capital improvements kept increasing with each subsequent class. The largest jump occurred in counties with population over one million. Although the mean per capita for capital improvement indebtedness followed the same pattern, the authors were a bit cautious that comparisons among jurisdictions on the basis of a single fiscal year may prove unreliable because capital expenditures of governmental units tend to move unevenly over time. The percentage of budget allocated to schools and roads indicated a negative relationship to population size, but that expended on health and welfare, police, fire, sewerage and sanitation, and parks and recreation showed positive association. The authors argued that the explanation for this observation depended on the facts that local governments in rural counties may discharge their principal responsibilities when they provide for the education of the children and see that their residents have adequate network of passable roads. Urbanization, on the other hand, brings with it the need and demand for sewerage disposal, public health measures, recreational facilities, better police and fire protection, and similar type of services. Schmandt and Stephens, found several important associations between per capita expenditures (total and firnctional categories) and the five independent variables. Amongst several conclusions that could be drawn from their analysis were: 28 (1) state aids, followed by median family income, emerged as the most important variable influencing per capita expenditures by county area aggregate. State aids and family income were measures of the availability of resources and reflect what communities can afl‘ord to expend on public services. (2) while per capita expenditures tended to rise in all functional categories with increase in median family income police and fire, welfare, highways, and public education were more influenced by State aids. (3) although they showed significant association with functional categories like protective services (police and fire), total population and density did not affect total per capita expenditures appreciably. The reason for this relationship was, according to the authors, that population and density were inversely related to expenditure for streets and highways because the per capita mileage to be maintained decreases as population and density rise. The protective services, on the other hand, were urban type firnctions and their magnitude increased as population and population density increased. (4) while state aid showed little relation to population size, median family income was significantly associated with population size and population density. This was a reflection of the greater economic opportunities and wealth that exist in the large urban centers. 29 (5) total current expenditure per capita showed higher association with territorial size of the counties than with total population and population density. Woo Sik Kee (1965) observed that most of the empirical studies regarding expenditure behavior of central cities had not been satisfactory because, (1) they were limited in scope (in terms of areas, class of governments, or firnctions they considered); (2) they did not recognize the fiscal interdependence between state and local governments on the one hand, and among the local governments on the other. Thus, in his attempt to augment the previous studies with a research that considered intergovernmental financial interdependence and one with broader scope he set two specific purposes for his study. They were: (1) discussing critical differences of socio-economic and governmental characteristics between the city and areas outside the central city’, and (2) showing the relationships between the level of per capita city expenditures and selected explanatory variables by incorporating the effects of intergovernmental fiscal responsibilities into multiple regression analysis. Thirty six Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas (SMSAs) showing variations in geographic location, population size, patterns of state and local governmental system, were selected. Public services of these 36 SMSAs were provided by a total of 4,482 local units of governments. Using the 1957 Census Bureau data six explanatory variables (per capita income, owner-occupied housing units as percent of total occupied units, population density, ratio of central city population to total SMSA population, ratio of 2 The definition of 'central city‘ established by the US Bureau of the Census, which Kee adopted, was a city or adjoining (twin) cities within 20 miles of each other that contain total of 50,000 or more inhabitants 30 state and local functional responsibility, and per capita state aid) were regressed on three dependent variables (total general expenditures, non-educational expenditures, and non- aided expenditures). The central cities and the rest of the metropolitan areas had substantial variations ($61.22 for Savannah, GA to $256 for Sacramento, CA and New York) with regard to per capita total expenditure and other major expenditure categories such as education, welfare, health, and highways. The variations were attributed to the differences in population characteristics, degree of urbanization, the level of income, and social and economic preferences in the study areas. Yet, the major hypothesis of the study was that the large part of the differences in per capita local expenditures within metropolitan areas was attributable to the differences in the distribution of governmental responsibilities between the state and its political subdivisions and the attendant share of state aid. Although it was true that substantial variations existed between central cities and the rest of the metropolitan areas (sub-urban areas) in total per capita expenditure, it was not evident from the data that central cities spent more than the rest of the metropolitan all the time. For example, while the total expenditure of New York sub-urban areas was $259.38, it was only $256.22 for New York City. Likewise, cities of Albany, Bridgeport, Buffalo, Norwalk, Stamford, Syracuse and Utica spent less than their sub-urban areas. This observation was a serious challenge to the earlier findings of Hawley (1952) and Brazer (1959 and 1962) that state (1) the total per capita expenditure of the central cities was closely related to the ratio of the central cities to the total population of their metropolitan districts, and (2) higher total expenditures were consistently incurred in the central cities (Brazer, 1962). According to Kee’s argument the mere fact that central 31 cities, in many instances, spend relatively more than the sub-urban areas does not establish the evidence that the residents of the sub-urban areas impose a net expenditure burden on the central cities. In cases where the sub-urban communities spend more than the central cities, he argued that it was so because of the relatively greater state aid to the areas outside the city. Woo Sik Kee cautioned that expenditure burdens of central cities and sub-urban areas are much more difficult to be explained by simple comparison of expenditures in that central cities, quite often, incur additional functions like urban renewals that could make the level of expenditure look higher at one point in time, where as some features of sub- urban areas (voluntary community services like fire fighting and privately operated sanitation) are ignored, there by making the level of expenditure look lower. Instead, he suggested that contrasting individual firnctions would be a more adequate method of comparison between the two places. Accordingly, he computed the coefficient of variation3 for each firnction in the central cities and sub-urban areas to compare the relative dispersions of the various classes of expenditure. The computation revealed that, excepting for health and hospitals, the coefficients of variations for per capita total general expenditure, total education, highways, and public welfare were higher for the sub-urban areas than the cities. Kee claimed that these variations of per capita expenditures of each category indicate that there is a great difference in the allocation of functional responsibilities between state and local governments. 3 The coefficient of variation (V) is a measure of variation used to compare inter-functional and inter- jun'sdictional per capita expenditures. The formula used to calculate was V = slx‘, where s is the standard deviation aid x‘ is the arithmetic mean of the 36 selected central cities and areas outside the cities. 32 Masten and Quindry (1970), using the 1966 per capita expenditures gathered through the Wisconsin State Department of Revenue, studied city expenditure determinants of 567 cities and villages in the State of Wisconsin in 1970. The sub- groupings of these 567 cities and villages consisted of 477 cities and villages with total population of less than 5,000, 62 cities and villages with total population of 5,000 - 20,000, and 25 cities and villages with population of 20,000 - 100,000. The relative importance of expenditure determinants for cities and villages of difl‘erent population sub- groupings were examined with the use of basic regression and correlation models. When all cities and villages were analyzed together, the regression analysis revealed that the estimated [is of the five independent variables, namely, total population, population density, per capita adjusted gross income, per capita full value of assessed property, and land area were 0.179, 0.161, 0.138, 0.688, 0.485 respectively. This showed that the per capita full value of property has the highest explanatory power than all other variables. The ranking of the independent variables in accordance to their contribution of increasing the coefficient of multiple determination (R) was found to vary by city and population sizes. For places with population less than 5,000 the ranking by descending order was per capita firll value of assessed property, per capita adjusted gross income, land area, population density, and total population. For places with population 5,000 - 20,000 it was per capita firll value of assessed property, total population, population density, per capita adjusted gross income, and land area. For places with population 20,000 - 100,000 it was population density, per capita full value of assessed property, per capita adjusted gross income, land area, and total population. 33 This study highlighted that the ability to pay taxes (revenue for city services) was very important for the first and second sub-groupings, and second most important, following population density, for the third sub-grouping. In contrast, total population (excepting for its second place in the second sub-grouping) was the least important in influencing the coefficient of multiple determination. Population density variable was the strongest expenditure determinant for 25 cities and villages in the 3rd sub-grouping. More importantly, as cities became more populated, the changing positions and importance of the determinants suggested unique growth process. For instance, for the first two sub-groupings with population less than 20,000 the ability to pay for city services, as measured by property value, was the most inrportant variable. When rapid urbanization phase was reached and the city expanded beyond a certain population size, street improvement, improved sewerage facilities, modernized fire fighting equipment, and other departmental expansions necessitated more than proportional increase in per capita expenditures and this phenomenon was represented by the increasing importance of the density factor as an explanatory variable in cities of the next higher population sub-grouping (20,000- 100,000). Confirming some findings of some other earlier studies, in particular that of Schmandt and Stephens (1963), they suggested that the interrelationship between per capita value assessed property, population density, and total population on the one hand and per capita expenditures as city size changed on the other reflected economies or diseconomies of scale in the provision of city services. The deviations and confusions between most of previous studies on factors influencing expenditures of local governments, according to Masten and Quindry, were 34 attributed to the general lack of data of cities and villages and the varying circumstances under which the studies were conducted. For instance, they cited the rejection of city size by pervious studies while it was later found to be very important in determining the relative explanatory ability of other socioeconomic factors as an example. Finally, they underscored the fact that the expenditure impact of the five basic variables considered as significant in previous expenditures studies, varied with city sizes; and all but one, land area, were found to be significant explanatory factors for cities and villages in the State of Wisconsin. The most recent study of the association between public service expenditures and selected explanatory variables was the one conducted by A. Allan Schmid (1997) for the State of Michigan. This study was original not only in its methodological approach but also in the type and quality of data it used. Seventeen cities and twenty-nine townships, representing different geographic locations and population size groups in Michigan, were purposefully selected out of the 71 communities in the State that have grown by a population of at least 1,000 between 1981 and 1990 and have a population of 5,000 or more. Fifteen years total expenditures data (excluding enterprise funds) was used in this study. The data was collected directly from the annual reports of cities and townships included in the research. The data was superior in quality when compared with all other data used in prior studies because: (1) they were actual expenditures (as opposed to budgeted expenditures) audited by certified public accountants and filed with the Michigan Department of Treasury; (2) the total operation expenditure were adjusted for the general inflation and were in 1995 constant dollar; and (3) the total capital improvement 35 expenditure was adjusted and amortized over a stand period (30 years) to avoid the erratic nature of capital investment expenditure. Multiple regression of cross sectional data for 1990 and 1995 were performed to determine the association between the dependent variable (total expenditures per capita) and the selected explanatory variables (total population, population growth rate, location, total state equalized value of property, and percent of state equalized value of residential WOW) The study had revealed several findings that were both in agreement and disagreement with previous studies. For instance, where most of previous studies indicate that there is strong association between population and expenditures in general, Schmid found that the relationship between city population and expenditures were negatively correlated and statistically not significant. His simple regression of population over expenditures per capita showed that only 12% of the variation in city expenditures was explained by population size. However, when similar analysis was done for townships separately from cities, total population and per capita expenditures showed statistically significant and positively correlated association. The simple regression of population over expenditures per capita also showed that 57%‘ of the variation in township expenditures ‘ The table below was reproduwd here just to show the impressive predication ability of the single variable regression model that explained only 57% of the variations in expenditures of townships. The per cmita expenditure prediction was calculated by multiplying the total population of the given township by the [3 value (which is 0.003) of the model (p. 33). Predicted Actual 1990 Township Per Capita per capita Expenditure Expenditure Clinton 342 321 Waterford 282 313 W. Bloomfield 252 278 36 were explained by population size. According to the author, while the offsetting of some of the increasing cost tendencies in cities by some other decreasing costs over some size ranges may explain the observed relationship of population and expenditures, new service needs and associated jump in expenditures as townships grow indicate the positive association between population and expenditures. Moreover, unlike the townships, large and small cities provide similar services and there will not be dramatic jumps in expenditures as they grow in size. Therefore, it will not be inconsistent that population size and expenditures exhibit inverse relationship. The multiple regression results of this study showed that all the selected explanatory variables jointly explained 75 and 60 percents of the variations in the 1990 expenditures of townships and cities respectively with similar results for 1995. For the townships, population size, state equalized property value, and proportion of residential properties were statistically significant. While population and property value were positively associated with expenditures, proportion of residential property was negatively correlated. The broad specification of location (as Southeast Michigan or not) and population growth rate, however, did not contribute to the explanations of per capita expenditures of townships significantly. For the cities, the only statistically significant variable was location. Population was not significant and population grth rate (also not significant) was negatively correlated. The model revealed a slightly different results for 1995: population growth rate, location, and proportion of residential property were barely significant. Meridian 192 255 Macomb 162 110 Fruitport 132 122 37 Similar analysis was performed using per household expenditures as the dependent variable with the same explanatory variables. For cities, using the 1990 data, none of the explanatory variables was significant. But, for townships, with a slightly decreased ability of the joint explanatory variables in explaining expenditures (69% vs. 75%), the same variables (population size, state equalized property value, and proportion of residential property value) remained significant. The rate of expenditure analysis of the study revealed that: ( 1) increase in expenditures for fastest growing townships was no different than the average for all townships, (2) large townships had higher expenditures regardless of their rate of growth, (3) the rate of growth in expenditures and population followed the same direction for cities, and (4) regardless of their grth pattern, larger cities did not exhibit higher expenditures. In order to give more insight into the relationship between expenditures and population size, the study presented some historical perspectives of the fifteen years total expenditures and individual expenditures of some functional categories (general government, public safety, roads and streets, and water and sewer) by dividing the sample communities into seven population size groups without distinction between the form of government (city or township) and location. The functional categories, according to the author, were public service types that mark certain expenditure threshold as population or density increase. The analysis revealed some observations that explain the relationship between expenditures of functional categories and population size. For example, it showed that the 38 expenditure for public safety in townships increases at a decreasing rate with rise in population; and while mid-sized cities have shown increase in roads and streets per capita expenditure over a range of period, large and small size group cities do not show any firm pattern in per capita spending. Schmid started out the study with two major questions: (1) do population size and location of local governments have effect on public service expenditures? and (2) if they do, could public service expenditures be reduced by altering macro-pattems of future settlement (or development)? The answer to both questions was yes. Population size and location may affect cities and townships differently, but there is evidence from the study that the macro pattern of population location and the micro pattern of size and density of population are policy tools that can reduce the public service expenditures levels. 39 2.2 Lessons From the Studies It can be summed from the foregoing review that population size and growth rate have been found to be the most important variables that explain variations in public service expenditures by Berlozheimer (1947) and Schmid (1997), as it only related to townships. 0n the other hand, for Hawley (1951), Brazer (1959), Schmandt and Stephens (1963), Kee (1965), and Masten and Quindry (1970) population size and growth rate were of the least importance. Instead, excepting for Masten and Quindry, population density and the ratio of the population of the community to that of its metropolitan district were very important. In addition to the authors reviewed above, other distinguished early researchers had also attempted to show which of these variables influence public service expenditures most. For instance, Mabel L. Walker (1930), in her study of municipal expenditures, had found that per capita costs of government increase rapidly as the population increases. Supporting her conclusion, Donald H. Davenport (1947) studied 56 cities around New York and determined that there was positive correlation between per capita expenditures of cities and population size. Hansen and Perloff (1944) and Solomon Fabricant (1952) have also confirmed these findings. Contrary to the conclusion of these researchers, Gerhard Colm et al (1936), aflirmed that density of population is of utmost importance in the cost of public services to the taxpayer. Nevertheless, since the authors believed that industrialization and wealth influence density of population, they had enjoined that it is diflicult to isolate the genuine influence of density on public costs and it could be further assumed that density can decrease per capita costs in certain area of functional categories. Five years later, Arnold 4O Brecht (1941) also published a research, which supports Colm er a] by concluding that it is only density of population that is highly correlated with per capita expenditures of municipal services. Scott and Feder (1957), on the other hand, published a totally different finding. They studied 192 California cities with 1950 population of 2,500 or more and examined the relationship between the municipal expenditures per capita (excluding public service enterprise expenditures and those financed through special assessments) and the explanatory variables they considered. The independent variables they used in the model were retail sales per capita, rate of growth of population, median number of persons per occupied dwelling unit, total population, population density, and adjusted property valuation per capita. They attributed expenditure differences in California cities to variations in tax paying ability of the population. The analysis showed that it was the adjusted property valuation per capita that had statistically significant regression coefficient. But four years later, Shapiro (1961) came with an other different conclusion ranking land area of a local government as the most important explanatory variable. It can be said that little agreement existed amongst the researchers reviewed here as to which independent variables are most important in explaining local government expenditures. As a result, there is no single formula or rule that satisfactorily explains the casual relationships involved. Nevertheless, there are some variables that are more fi'equently offered as the leading factors. That includes, total population, population grth rate, population density, median household (family) income, land (territorial) area, inter-governmental revenues, and property value. 41 To their credit, most of the authors recognize that public service expenditures are determined not only by the economic elements which have been considered here, but also by many political, social, and personal factors (Walker, 1930; Colm et al, 1936; Brazer, 1959; Schmid, 1997). Although these social, political, and personal influences could have efl‘ect only within a fiamework set by the economic factors determining the requirements for and costs of public services and the resources available for financing them, the . ambition of an able governor, mayor or legislator, for example, may have an important influence on the kind and size of public expenditures in a state or local government. Unfortunately, there is no definite and ready measure of such variables that could help the analysts to quantify its effect on the casual relationships between public service expenditures and the factors involved. Notwithstanding Woo Sik Kee’s criticism, most of the studies reviewed, excepting that of Schmid, are of national or regional scope. Studying public service expenditures at larger levels of system of government (state, regional, or federal) could have both advantages and disadvantages. On the advantage side, (1) it creates ease of comparing public service expenditures among states and regions for which data are readily available fi'om the Census Bureau, and(2) it eliminates the influence of differences in the distribution of service responsibilities among the various types of local governments of city, township, or school district (Schmandt and Stephens, 1963). On the disadvantage side, it hinders the ability of a researcher to compare expenditure patterns among and between the smallest units of governments and suppresses the role of each variable that has different explanatory ability for different size and types of local government. For instance, Masten and Quindry found that population density was 42 the most important variable in explaining the expenditure behavior of all the 25 cities and villages with a population range of 20,000 - 99,999 in the State of Wisconsin in 1966. But, at the same time, they found that population density ranked fourth, out of five explanatory variables, in its ability to explain the expenditure behavior of all the 567 cities and villages in Wisconsin considered together. Hence, it will be difficult to accept results based on the findings of larger set of cities without qualification. Similarly, the Michigan study by Schmid (1997) revealed that population size was the most important variable that explained the expenditure patterns of 29 Michigan townships, while it, at the same time, showed no significant association with the expenditures of the 17 cities considered in the study. Distribution of service responsibilities vary among cities and townships. Accordingly, their revenue collection ability and patterns of expenditures are different. Therefore, it will be inaccurate to put all local governments in one pot and analyze the casual relationships of the variables that are of interest without making any distinction to their form and structure. Finally, the type of data used by most of the researchers are susceptible to inadequacy. First, the data were collected by the Bureau of Census and it is not clear as to how much these data are fitting the objectives of the researchers without any adjustment. Some of the researchers have noticed the discrepancy between the data they needed and what was available to them. This discrepancy had created definite constraints on their ability to carry out a reliable analysis. Secondly, most of the researchers relied on a single year cross-sectional data to perform the analysis. Some were aware of the drawbacks that the use of a single year data was imposing on their analysis. As a result, some of them were forced to abandon the consideration of capital improvement expenditures from their 43 analysis all together. Others have some how went ahead with the one year data available to them and cautioned that the findings be seen only as an ad hoc. Even if the problem surrounding abandonment or use of capital improvement expenditure is to be tolerated, how much could the results of all other expenditures based on a single year data be reliable? The main point of departure between the current study and the prior studies is around this question. The method of analysis applied and types of data used are very difl'erent. The current study used fifteen years time-series cross-section data on population, expenditures, and state equalized value of properties along with other supplementary data of individual service categories. 1t performed rigorous and extensive statistical and regression analysis of panel data for forty six fast growing local governments of different population size groups, geographic location, and types of government in the State of Michigan. CHAPTER 3 CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK TO ESTHVIATE DETERMINANTS OF PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES 3.1 Introduction This chapter develops a conceptual framework that can be used to estimate the determinants of per capita public service expenditures (expenditures, here after) in the fast growing communities of Michigan. The model derived can also be viewed as a local government expenditure decision model. Expenditures patterns of communities are expected to vary by types of government (city or townships) and are further sub-classified by geographic location and population size groups. Furthermore, expenditures are assumed to be functions of total population size, population growth rate, population density, residential property as percent of total property, and value of properties. 3.2 The Expenditures Model Following the general models developed by Masten and Quindry (1970) and Schmid (1997), the model of analysis of was specified as follows: expend = fipoptotal, popgrwth, popdenst, rsdntprp, totalprp) Where: poptotal = total population popgrwth = population grth rate popdenst = population density 44 45 rsdntprp = residential property totalprp = total property The general objective of local governments was assumed to be providing the best possible public services (maximizing service benefits) with minimum expenditures. However, efliciency of the governing bodies (or public service providers) on the one hand and quality and quantity of the public services provided on the other were variables that were very diflicult to measure, at least for this study. Consequently, they were not included in the model specification. 3.3 The Dependent Variable The dependent variable was the per capita total expenditures for public services. It was computed by dividing total expenditures by total population of each study community. The total expenditures were adjusted for inflation and were in 1995 constant dollars. The functional categories for which the total expenditures were computed included general government, public safety, public works, welfare and social services, culture and recreation, capital outlay, and debt service. 3.4 The Independent Variables There were five independent variables considered in this study. They were total population, population growth rate, population density, residential property as percent of total property, and equalized value of total properties. 46 3.4.1 Total Population Total population of communities was one of the variables that was often offered as the most important variable that affects expenditures in much of the literature (Donald H. Davenport, 1926; Brazer, 1959; Census Bureau, 1951; Schmid, 1997). It was, therefore, hypothesized that the higher the population size, the higher the expenditures will be. Furthermore, changes in per capita expenditures and total population were expected to move in the same direction. The hypothesis relied on the assumption that demands for more and improved public services will increase as the population of a community grows. The increase of demand for public services, holding quality of public services constant, will place more pressure on local government budget and will increase public service expenditures. Most of the public services (public safety, water and sewer, and roads for example) are congestablc goods with capacity constraints. These classes of goods may be having scale economies over a certain range of population and may have a zero marginal cost as the number of users increases from zero to some given number (capacity threshold). But, as population keeps increasing, the addition of more users reduces the utility of services and quality of life of all users and the marginal cost of additional users begins to rise. As the absolute capacity constraint is reached, the marginal cost of additional user will increase sharply (Randall, 1987). Then, governments are expected to invest more on public services and their related infrastructures to at least keep the quality and per user quantity of services constant when faced with growing population. 47 Diseconomies of scale may also be a factor that raises the expenditures of communities that have passed a certain population threshold. As the total population of a community increases beyond a certain level, different types of services may become economically feasible or necessary. Some communities may grow to a population size that may require them to provide their own services (like police and/or fire protection, for instance) instead of contracting from other agencies or jurisdictions. Or new types of land development that may have been necessitated by population growth (more multi-family dwellings vs single family dwellings, or more commercial developments vs residential developments) may require better and more fire trucks, more and wider streets than the existing ones, etc. Most of the infrastructures of public services are lumpy in nature. At times, improving infrastnrctures and services by increment may not be possible. It may become necessary to totally scrap the old infrastructures and build new ones. This will cause a large capital expenditure. Furthermore, the per capita expenditures on the construction, maintenance, and service of these new lumpy infrastructures could stay high because it may take a while for the optimal number of people making use of them to settle. Population could also have indirect impacts on expenditures through other factors that have direct relationship with expenditures. For instance, income could be a firnction of population (Brazer, 1959). Mostly, economic opportunities are higher where population is the highest. As a result, income could be high where economic opportunities are high. Then, the high income population could be more willing to demand and able to pay for higher quality of public services. 48 3.4.2 Population Growth Rate Although it was assumed that the needs and demand for public services increase as the population of communities grow, it was hypothesized that expenditures and the rate of population growth will not necessarily flow in the same direction. Even if population may be growing at a faster rate, new expenditures on infrastructures may not be necessary as existing facilities could be used more intensively because the existing service facilities may have excess capacities, or simply budgetary allocations commonly do not keep pace with the expansion of service requirements (Brazer, 1959; Schmid, 1997). Budget allocation is a function of several factors, including political choices and tax payers willingness to finance the service investment. That means, the service expenditures do not necessarily grow proportionately with the rate of increase of population. Some earlier studies have indicated that governmental infrastructures and institutions, once established for minimum purposes, grow with population but at a rate less than population. Therefore, inverse relationship between population grth rate and expenditures was expected. 3.4.3 Population Density Population density, as a measure of the extent to which people live close to each other, was considered in this study because levels of expenditures of the major public services were reported to be functions of density in several earlier studies. In the case of highways and streets, for example, it had been reported that as the density of population increases road per capita expenditure will decline (Colm, et al, 193 6). As density increases 49 per capita mileage of roads to be maintained should fall and it is unlikely that greater traffic volume resulting from higher density will offset this benefit (Brazer, 1959). On the other hand, the need for police and fire protection, for example, may be increasing as population density rises. Therefore, it is hypothesized that population density and total per capita public service expenditures are highly associated; but the sign of the correlation depends on the budget share of each functional category. If, for instance, police and fire protections constitute major share of the total public service expenditures, it should be expected that the sign of estimated coefficient and correlation would be positive. 3.4.4 Property Value and Land Use Characteristics Land use in the State of Michigan could be divided into four major groups; agricultural, commercial, industrial, and residential. Different types of land use will require different types of public services. If, for instance, a community is characterized as rural and agricultural, its road, fire and police protection, or water and sewer requirements will be different from those of commercial or industrial communities. Industrial communities may require more governmental services than agricultural communities. The demands for highways, sanitary services, communication, protection, etc. increase inevitably with industrialization and urbanization. Therefore, it was hypothesized that there is a systematic relationship between land use and public service expenditures. Residential property is expected to have inverse relationship with expenditures whereas industrial and commercial properties will be positively related to expenditures. 50 The state equalized value of all types of preperties are used as proxies to measure the impacts of land use characteristics on expenditures. Property value captures both the wealth and tax paying ability of a community and many earlier studies have established that general government expenditures of a community are closely related to income and wealth in that jurisdiction (Schmid, 1997). Therefore, since public services are predominantly determined by the resources available for expenditures, it was hypothesized that the value of total property will determine the relationship between the effective demand for public services and services provided by local governments. 3.5 Attributes of Services and Model Specification Most of the past studies of public service expenditures have recognized the possible relationship between efficiency of governments and quantity and quality of services on the one hand and per capita public service expenditures of local governments on the other. But, they did not attempt or, may be, they were unable to develop a method of analyzing the association between these attributes of local government and public services and the associated expenditures. For example, the same amount of dollar outlays to construct a water and sewer infrastructure in different geographic or topographic areas may not produce the same physical amount or unit of infrastructure at these different places. If it did, then, the infi'astnrctures at these different places must be of difl‘erent quality or are done with a varying degree of efficiency. But, how can we measure this type of association between these attributes and expenditures at national, regional, state, or local levels? Unfortunately, much remains to be explored in solving this problem. Still to 51 date, there is no meaningful statistical or any other empirical method that could be used to measure the different elements of these attributes and their impacts on public service expenditures (Colm, et al., 1936 ; Brazer, 1959; Schmid, 1997). Consequently, this study analyzed impacts of selected economic variables on expenditures of local governments rather than on costs of a given quality and per capita quantity of services provided by local governments. Also, little data on service levels (per capita quantity of services provided) are available. For example, we may know the exact number of police officers in a given community and that number (and the expenditure) may appear to be too high in comparison with other similar community of equal size. But it will not be known if that community has decided to have that many officers because crime is more common in that community or just because the community chose to have a higher level of services such as faster response time. 3.6 Omitted Variables Two revenue variables that were used by many of the earlier researchers were not considered in this study for several reasons. These variables were inter-govemmental revenue transfers and household (family) income. 3.6.1 Inter-governmental Revenue Transfers Does the source of revenue affect the level of expenditures? Or conversely, would there be difference in expenditures whether the expenditures are paid for by revenues fi’om intergovernmental transfers or taxes collected from the residents? Intergovernmental 52 revenue transfer was not specified as an independent variable in this study. However, it has been offered by some of the earlier researchers as one of the leading factors influencing the level of expenditures. Indeed, it was one of the major contributors to revenues of most of fast growing local governments in Michigan (over 20% for many of the cities and townships). Nonetheless, this analyst did not find it to be compelling to consider this variable in the model because he argues that changes in expenditures of local governments would flow in the same direction with changes in intergovernmental revenue transfers. Ifthe revenue transferred to a local government from the state is high, that local government is now getting more money to spend on new services or to improve on the quality and quantity of existing services. Ifthe revenue transferred is less, that local government will have less to spend. Unless it is intended to investigate whether intergovernmental revenue transfer is associated with other economic variables (say, population size, density, or growth rate), which was not the objective of this study, there was no need to consider it in the model as an independent regression variable apart from the other public revenues. Furthermore, it had been indicated in some of the earlier studies that intergovernmental revenues and per capita expenditures are significantly and - positively correlated (Schmandt and Stephens, 1963; Woo Sik Kee, 1965). 3.6.2 Household (Family) Income Some of the earlier studies have used household (family) income in their studies of public service expenditures. Using this variable may have not caused any significant problem in their analysis because: (1) they did not include other economic variables that have strong correlation with it in their models; and (2) they were using a single year cross- 53 sectional data. However, this variable was excluded from the model of the current study exactly for the two reasons it was used by earlier researchers. First, a correlation analysis performed with the 1992 median household income in the 46 fast growing corrununities in Michigan showed a very high correlation (0.88) with the equalized value of residential property. Such high correlation creates a multicollinearity problem in the regression analysis and will make the model weak in explaining factors that drive the variations in expenditures of the communities . Second, household income data is neither available on yearly basis nor could it be projected. The current study requires the exact income data for the fifteen years period covered. Therefore, household income was dropped fiom the model and, instead, the equalized values of properties were used as proxy of wealth and income of the study communities. 3.7 Unit of Observation and Categories of Analysis The analysis in this study was conducted using a local governments as a unit of observation. All the data were for municipalities and townships. However, in order to make a meaningful comparison by creating homogeneity among the units of analysis, the local governments were categorized by type of government (city or township), two general geographic locations (Southeast Michigan or Rest of State), and two arbitrary population size groups (equal to or more than 50,000 and less than 50,000). 54 3.7.1 Types of Government Different local governments have different responsibilities and taxing power in provisions of public services. The two types of governments in Michigan that were included in this study are cities and townships. These governments operate under difl‘erent laws and they are different in their distribution of public service responsibilities. For example, cities have to provide their own road and street services, while the responsibility of constructing and maintaining roads and streets in townships is assigned to the County Road Commission since 1931 (Delphendahl, 1961). In most of the cases, cities have more responsibilities in providing public services to their residents when compared to townships and, as a result, they have higher expenditures. On average, in 1995, for instance, the sampled fast growing cities in Michigan spent more per resident than the townships. Townships may use some of the services provided by adjoining cities or counties free or with minimal pay. Consequently, they could have less expenditures. Furthermore, cities and townships differ in their taxing power. For example, a charter township can levy 5 to 10 mills with a vote of the people, while cities may levy up to 20 mills. These differences in service provision responsibilities and revenue collection authority have significant impacts on the patterns and extent of expenditures. The seventeen cities and twenty nine townships included in this study have significant difference in expenditures. Therefore, cities and townships can not be mixed and compared. . 55 3.7.2 Geographic Location Location of a local government was used as a sub-category of comparison. It was expressed as whether a place is in Southeast Michigan (SEM) or Rest of the State. Southeast Michigan is the most populous region of the state where more than 50% of the population is currently residing. Cities and townships in this region are more clustered than anywhere in the state. That is, local governments in Southeast Michigan are located close to each other and exhibit a degree of settlement congestion. Per capita public service expenditures of communities in a relatively congested area would be expected to be higher because a considerable portion of the expenditures would be caused by residents of the adjoining communities. The residents of the adjoining communities are attracted by activities and facilities in that particular community. The effective population of a local government, where high settlement density is observed, is considerably greater than what is contained within the incorporated boundaries of that political jurisdiction (Hawley, 1952; Schmid, 1997). The impacts of the economic variables in explaining expenditures by location was investigated by separating the sample cities and townships into the two locations mentioned above. Location does not vary from period to period and remains to be a constant in the panel. Moreover, the econometric model chosen for the study, Fixed Eflects regression, does not allow the use of individual level covariates in the model. Therefore, it was not considered as an independent regression variable in the model. 56 3.7.3 Population Size Groups Population has a unique position in the public service expenditures of all local governments. Unlike geographic location, for instance, it can serve as a sub-category of comparison and, because it varies fiom year to year, can be used as an independent variable of regression in the model at the same time. Many of the earlier studies have presented different reports on the association between expenditures and different sizes of population. The impact and ranking of the explanatory power of other variables, for instance, were reported in some of the earlier studies to have been dependent on the sizes of population. Thus, in order to comprehend the significance of the variable in shaping expenditures of communities, it was decided to thoroughly analyze the relationship between population and expenditures in this study at two levels with a data set that considers the continues changes in population. CHAPTER FOUR ANALYTICAL METHODS FOR ESTIMATING DETERMINANTS OF VARIATIONS IN PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES 4.1 Introduction The main purpose of this chapter is to develop an empirical method of estimating the determinants of per capita public service expenditures in the fast growing local governments in the State of Michigan. Two major tasks are accomplished in the chapter. First, the data used in the empirical analysis are described in detail and all the procedures and processes involved in cleaning, adjusting, and organizing all the data are presented in several sub-sections. Finally, the econometric method employed for the analysis is discussed and the regression equation is developed. 4.2 The Data The data used in this study include: US Census population figures of 1980 and 1990 for all the fast growing communities in Michigan and the 1994 population projection of the Michigan Department of Management; public service expenditures of all service categories (general government, public safety, public works, recreation and culture, capital outlay, debt service, etc) from the Comprehensive Annual Financial Report (1981 to 1995) 57 58 of the forty-six communities; state equalized value of agricultural, commercial, industrial, personal, and total properties (1981 - 1995) of the all the forty-six communities; public safety data of 1990 and 1995 for all cities and townships in the study; and roads and streets expenditure for selected communities. 4.2.1 Population The study covered the period between 1981 to 1995. Population data of the US Census Bureau were only available at ten years interval and the 1980 and 1990 population figures were used to determine the fast growing local governments that were included in the study. Communities with a population greater than 5,000 and had grown by 1,000 people between 1981 and 1990 were purposefirlly defined as fast growing local governments. However, townships of Alpine in Kent County and Muskegon and Fruitport in Muskegon County, which have grown by less than 1,000 residents, were included in the study for the purpose of having a reasonable geographic distribution and representation of the local governments in the study. That brought the total number of local governments in Michigan defined as fast growing communities to sixty-nine (17 cities and 52 townships). While all the seventeen cities (100%) were included in the study, a sample of twenty-nine townships out of total population of fifty-two (56%) were selected. These twenty-nine townships fairly represent different population sizes and geographic locations. 59 Table 4.1: All Fast Growing Cities in Michigan, 1980 - 1990 Pop Pop Pop Change City 1980 1990 1980 - 1990 Sterling Htsw 108,999 117,810 8,811 Portage 38,157 41,042 2,885 Wyoming 59,616 63,891 4,275 Troy 67,102 72,884 5,782 Farmington H181 58,056 74,652 16,596 Rochester Hill 40,779 61,766 20,987 Kenlwocd 31.438 37 .826 7,388 Novi 22,525 32,998 10,473 Holland 21,767 25,086 3,319 Graidville 12,412 15,624 3,212 Walker 15,088 17,279 2,191 Aubm Hlsr 15,598 17,076 1,478 Wixom 6,705 8,550 1,845 Marysviller 7,345 8,515 1,170 Lapeer 6,198 7,759 1,561 Brighton 4,268 5,686 1,418 Walled Lake 4,748 6,278 1,530 60 Table 4.2: All Fast Growing Townships in Michigan, 1980 - 1990 Pop Township Pop Pop Change 1980 1990 80 - 90 Clinton 72,400 85,866 13,466 Shelby 38,939 48,655 9,716 Waterford 64,437 66,692 2,255 W. Bloomfield 41,962 54,516 12,554 Canton 48,616 57,040 8,424 Meridian 28,754 35,644 6,890 Georgetown 26,104 32,672 6,568 Delta 23,822 26,129 2,307 Plainlield 20,611 24,946 4,335 Chesterfield 18,276 25,905 7,629 Harrison 23,649 24,685 1,036 Macomb 14,230 22,714 8,484 Contmerceu 23,757 26,955 3,198 Independence 21,537 24,722 3,185 Orion 22,473 24,076 1,603 Van Buren 18,940 21,010 2,070 Delhi 17,144 19,190 2,046 Holland 13,739 17,523 3,784 Pittsfield 12,997 17,668 4,671 Northville 12,987 17,313 4,326 Garfield 8,747 10,500 1,753 Allendalet 6,080 8,022 1,942 East Bay 6,212 8,307 2,095 Oshtemo 10,958 13,401 2,443 Alpine] 8,934 9,863 929 Byron 10,104 13,235 3,131 Cascade 10.120 12,869 2,749 Gaines 10,364 14,533 4,169 Grand Rapid 9,294 10,760 1,466 Spata 6,934 8,447 1,513 Hamburg 11,318 13,083 1,765 Washington 10,213 13,083 2,870 Brandon 9,526 12,051 2,525 Lyon 7,078 9,450 2,372 Milford 10,187 12,121 1,934 61 Table 4.2: (Cent'd) Pop Township Pop Pop Change 1980 1990 80 - 90 Oxford 10,569 1 1,933 1,364 Springfield 8,295 9,927 1,632 Grand Haven 7,238 9,710 2,472 Park 10,354 13,541 3,187 Antwerp 7,744 9,293 1,549 Scio 8,029 11,077 3,048 F ’ 10,646 11,485 839 Muskegon 14,557 15,302 745 Kinross 1,891 6,566 4,675 Long Lake 3,823 5,977 2,154 Texas 5,643 7,711 2,068 Ada 6,472 7,578 1,106 Algoma 4,411 5,496 1,085 Caledonia 4,927 6,254 1,327 Cannon 4,983 7,928 2,945 lra 4,316 5,587 1,271 Northlield 4,672 6,732 2.060 Table 4.3: Townships Selected for the Study. Clinton Delhi Shelby Holland Waterford Pittslield W. Bloomfield Northville Canton Alpine Meridian Cascade Georgetown Grand Rapid Delta Sparta Plainiield Milford Chesterfield Fruljgort Harrison Muskegon Macomb Long Lake Commerce lra Orion Norlhlield Garfield 62 A simple arithmetic method was used to compute the annual total population of each community. The annual population growth rate between 1980 - 1990 was obtained by computing the percentage change between 1980 and 1990 and dividing that by 10: [(popoo - popmypopgoylo. The annual total population between 1980 and 1990 were interpolated by multiplying the preceding year’s population by one plus the annual growth rate. For instance, if the annual growth rate of a community was 2%, 1981 population of that community will be 1980 population plus the computed annual growth, i.e., popan, = popm, x(1+0.02). Similar calculation was used for the period between 1991 and 1994 on the basis of the 1994 population projection of the Michigan Department of Management and Budget. The population figures of all the communities for 1995 were extrapolated by using the same growth rate calculated for the period between 1991 and 1994. 4.2.2 Expenditures Tables 4.4 through 4.8 display the expenditures data for fifteen years period (1981-1995).obtained from Comprehensive Annual Financial Report (CAFR) and annual audit of local govemments'. CAFR are prepared by certified independent public accountants and are approved by Michigan Department of Treasury. A 1994 revenue- expenditure balance sheet of all Governmental Funds Types for Meridian Township was ' There were few instances, like in the case of City of Walker, Kent County, where CAFR of some years were missing. Interpolation of estimated expenditures head on the averages of the prewding and succeeding years in conjunction with data from F-65 for the missing years had been applied to complete the data requirements. 63 presented in Table 4.4 as an example of a typical financial statement for a local government in Michigan.2 A closer look at the CAFR of all the local governments indicates that their revenue-expenditure accounts are organized on the basis of different types of funds and account groups. A firnd is a separate accounting entity with a self-balancing set of accounts. Each of the account groups are considered a separate accounting entity and contain information related to assets, liabilities, firnd equity, revenues, and expenditures. Public resources are allocated to an individual type of fund based upon the purpose for which they are to be used. They are grouped into seven fund types (General Funds, Special Funds, Debt Service Funds, Capital Project Funds, Enterprise Funds, Internal Service Funds, Trust Funds). These fimd types are grouped within three broad categories; namely, Government Funds, Proprietary Funds, and Fiduciary Funds. The Government Funds, the only funds category used in this study, is for those funds through which most typical governmental firnctions are financed. As shown in Table 4.4 above, four types of government funds are included in this category: General Fund; Special (Selected) Revenue Funds; Debt Service Funds; and Capital Projects Funds. Debt Service Funds are not used in the empirical analysis for reasons explained elsewhere in this chapter. 2 All the sample tables and figures on expenditures and state equalized values of properties presented in this chapter are those of Meridian Township. There is no particular reason why Meridian is chosen over the other locd govemrmnts. The same tables and figures are done for all the 46 local governments included in this study. It is decided to stick to one local govemment for the purpose of showing the logic and sequence of cleaning, adjusting, and organizing the data. All data pertaining to the 1994 fiscal year are highlighted. 64 4. 2. 2.1 General Fund This is the basic and primary operating fund for general government operations. It records financial resources used for day-to-day general government service activities, such as municipal administration, public safety, parks and recreation, environmental health, etc. This fund receives the majority of its financing from such sources as property taxation, state shared revenues, fees and charges for services, investment income, and an annual operating transfer from other departmental funds in accordance with provisions in the governmental charter. 65 «Sass. 838 88.8.. “8.5.. 2.. .858 2.... «swam 29.8... 833 88.8.. are? .858 as“. 35.88 8&8... and: 5.3 Eagegm E38. $5 ~88 36.3 8.22.. .25 .28 2%: 888.....8. 833.. 888389.. 8.8 33.33.: .333 sausage. 8:88 95.8. 338 «8.8 c. Secs. 2:280 82:8 2.22.... .26 was: 98.5.. 3.9 33.8..“ 8.3.225 .53 8mg 23. ”8.23832. 33.. 83 .89.... 828. 58 8mg 8m... $.25 3.50 3.80 «2.8. «8.8. .25 m8? 323958828”. 29.2.. E... 5.8: 83: «so; 0.8.. 25.88.... is. 2.9.. 8.29. 2.8.. 33 3.33 .§E§ .293 3.8. 93%. ago mmeEzmoxm 3.9.... 39.3... 3...”: 3.4.5: 3:559. .32 89.8» 8% £28. «8.6 885388 3.88 85.8. 83.. EN” 985% .83.... 2%: 3.3.. 8028 s. 899.0 986me 355.2692... 2mg 5389...; .33” 3.3% 83 8.3... 3.80 8:8 So as“. .388 as“. .228 8.52 32 .9323» $5.52 deg—.590 9...... 95:23. 3 .583me 3:358 H: 23 4.2.2.2 Special Revenue Funds These are fund types used to account for the proceeds of specific revenue sources (other than special assessments, expendable trusts, and major capital projects) that are legally restricted to expenditures for specified purposes. They include funds like the Highway and Major Streets Fund, Highway and Local Streets Fund, both established by State of Michigan Public Act 51 of 1951, County Road Tax Fund established by the State of Michigan Public Act 283 of 1909, Public Library Fund, Police Criminal Justice Training Fund, etc. 4.2.2.3 Debt Service Funds These are fund types used to account for the accumulation of resources for and the payment of principal, interest, and related costs of general long-term debt obligation and special assessment long-term debt. The general obligation debt service fund accounts for the servicing of current maturity requirements (that include principal, interest, and agent fees) on general obligation bonds like building authority bonds and other bonds issued by Authority of State of Michigan Act 40. The revenues to finance such debt service obligations are derived from property taxation, transfers from other funds, and investment income. Special assessment debt service funds account for the servicing of outstanding long-term debt in the form of special assessment bonds. Revenues to finance these debt service obligations arise from special assessments levied against benefiting 67 property owners in approved special assessment districts for which the bonds were originally issued. 4.2.2.4 Capital Projects Funds These are fimds used to account for financial resources utilized for the acquisition or construction of major capital assets or infia-structures other than those projects financed by Proprietary Funds and Expendable Trust Funds. Financing for these kinds of projects include operating transfers from other funds, special assessments, private sector donations, and grant funding. Each of the projects in this group of funds are normally budgeted and accounted for as multi-fiscal year to encompass revenues and expenditures that span the entire open period of the specific project fi'om inception to completion. However, project revenues and expenditures are also recognized by individual fiscal year for annual financial purposes. 4.2.3 Adjusting Expenditures Although the data in the CAFR of the local governments are of high quality and reliable, they needed to be adjusted and rearranged in a way that they fit the objectives of the study. Consequently, some of the data specific to some service categories were excluded; some of the fimd types and categories were netted out; all of the expenditures and equalized values of property data were adjusted for inflation; and the capital project expenditures were amortized. 68 4.2.4 Excluded Fund Types Three types of funds were purposefully excluded from the study. They were Enterprise Funds, Internal Service Funds, and Fiduciary Funds. The first two types of funds are used to account for the local government’s ongoing organizations and activities similar to those found in the private sector. They are accounted for on a cost of service or capital maintenance measurement focus. All assets and liabilities associated with their activity are included on their balance sheets, and operating statements present increases and decreases in net total assets. Enterprise funds account for: (a) operations that are financed and operated in a manner similar to business entities, where the intent of the service provider is that the expenses, including depreciation, of providing goods and services to the general public on a continuing basis be financed primarily through user charge; or, (b) operations where the governing body has decided that periodic determination of revenues earned, expenses incurred, and/or net income is appropriate for capital maintenance or other purposes. Examples of such funds are water and sewer fund, power utility funds, parking lots fund, municipal airport fund, depot operations fund, and recycling pickup fund. Internal Service Funds are used to account for the financing of goods and services provided by one department or activity of a city or township to other departments or activities of the government; and/or to other governmental units on a cost-reimbursement basis. These funds are established, managed, and Operated as a proprietary type operation, providing financial accountability for (a) operating and non-operating revenues and expenses, (b) current assets, restricted assets, capital assets, liabilities, and fund equity. 69 Examples of these funds include information services fund, equipment revolving fund as mandated by State of Michigan Act 51 of 1951, postage services fund, telephone services fund, fire vehicle and equipment fiJnd, vehicle and property insurance fund, health and dental insurance fund etc. Fiduciary Funds, also referred to as Trust and Agency Funds, are used to account for assets held by the local government in a trustee capacity or as an agent for individuals, private organizations, other governments, and/or other funds. These include Expendable Trust, Non-expendable Trust, and Agency funds. The Expendable Trust Fund is accounted for in essentially the same manner as a Governmental Fund, which means both principal and earnings are spendable. The Pension Trust Fund is accounted for in the same manner as Proprietary funds (only earnings are spendable). The Agency Funds are custodial in nature and do not involve measurement of results of operations. Disbursements from these funds are made in accordance with trust agreements or applicable legislative enactment for each individual fund. Examples of these funds are: Expendable Trust Funds: utilities guaranteed fund, police community relations fund, and municipal airport donations fund; Non-expendable Trust Fund: cemetery perpetual care fiJnd, library endowment fund; and Agency Fund: current tax collections fund, employee deferred compensation plan fund, and employee flexible spending fund. Moreover, including Enterprise Funds such as water and sewer fund creates problem when comparing expenditures across communities. The service boundaries of such service categories may not necessarily coincide with the political boundaries of local governments (Schmid, 1997). Some local governments may not serve all the residents of their political boundary and others may extend the service to residents of other political 70 jurisdictions. Pittsfield Township, for instance, has an area where its sewer service does not reach and those residents use their own septic systems. On the other hand, the water authority of the Detroit Metropolitan Water authority is serving many of the local governments in Southeast Michigan. 4.2.5 Netting Out Expenditures A special care was taken to avoid double counting and over stating expenditures. The special revenue and debt service sections of the expenditures account present such a problem. Debt service appears as both fimctional category and (find types at the same time (see Table 4.4). It accounts for principal retirement and interest and fees paid out of both the special revenue and debt service firnds. It was assumed here that debt services are mostly related to capital project outlays. Careful examination of the CAFR of each local government in the study did not indicate otherwise. Moreover, capital project outlays are significant in the calculation of expenditures of all local governments. For example, the beginning and ending fund balances of the 1994 financial statement of Meridian Township indicate that the capital project fund accounts for more than 50% of the total Ending Fund Balance. Similarly, the financial statements of the 46 local governments for the fifteen years show that capital projects outlay is an essential part of local governments expenditures. Unlike most of prior studies that have ignored it, it is deemed necessary to consider the capital project expenditures along with the total operating expenditures of all local governments in the study. 71 However, including both the capital project outlays and debt service expenditures in the calculation of the total capital project expenditures poses the problem of overstating the total expenditures of the local governments. The debt service expenditures could include: (1) the capital outlays incurred prior to the study period; and (2) part of payment on capital project expenditures already entered under its own fiJnd type, depending on when such expenditure was incurred in the fiscal year. Hence, it was necessary to: (l) exclude the debt service fund all together, (2) net out the capital outlay expenses in the special revenue account; and (3) amortize all entries under the capital project firnds to account for only the study period expenditures and avoid over/under stating yearly expenditures. Table 4.6 was presented below to show the necessary first step in adjusting public service expenditure accounts, especially columns e and f. 5.2.6 Inflation Adjustment The operating and capital project expenditures of all the study communities were adjusted by a national index of deflators shown in Table 4.5. This was done for the purpose of accounting for inflation and generating comparable expenditure figures in terms of constant dollars. The operating and capital project expenditures have different deflators and were computed accordingly. For example, in 1994 Meridian Township had a total operating expenditures of $9,710,919 (Table 4.6). When adjusted for inflation, the expenditure was equal to $10,011,257 in 1995 dollars. Adjusted and amortized total expenditures of Meridian Township are displayed in Table 4.7 as a sample. It must be noted, however, that the adjustment of capital project expenditures was difl‘erent from that 72 of operating expenditures. It involved two steps of operations. First, the yearly total capital project expenditures were amortized. Then, the amortized yearly expenditures were adjusted by the corresponding deflators. This will be discussed in the next section. Table 4.5: Deflators of Operating and Capital Project Expenditures Operation Exp. Capital Project Exp. Year. Deflator 1%) Deflator (96) 1981 59.5 73.1 1982 63.1 73.4 1983 65.5 74.0 1984 68.7 76.4 1985 71.6 80.6 1986 73.9 82.2 1987 76.6 83.0 1988 79.9 86.8 1989 83.2 89.5 1990 86.7 91.0 1991 89.7 91.6 1992 92.2 91.5 1993 94.6 93.6 1994 97.0 96.7 1995 100.0 100.0 Source: Survey of Current Businesses 73 .82 - $2. .58”. 3.82m 3.2 2.2.2228 5.2.2.. .0 £2.38 2.20 .858 2.8.. 88.2»... 83.3 §...~ 25.3 82.8.. $.80... 3.82 3.3. 22:... 2...... . 8...... 5.2 39.83 32 5.8 3.3.30.2 2.8.3.2 8% 25.5 . 8.5... 82 2.3 . .862... «8.22 8% «8.22 ggo... 82 RE: . 2.38... 3.3 - 8...... 2.3... 48.2.... 32 33.. 2.8.48.“ - 182.8 8% .82... 3.8.3...“ 82 .8 egg... - .8... 3.2 32....“ 20.38... 82 3.8 . 862.8 88.8 - «8.2 28.2 ~83... 82 3.2. 2.80... #5.: - an: 8...; 5.2% 52 28.5 822m... 8......” 2 82.2 08.8 5.2% 82 28.2” $.23... 8.3.. 8 «2.2 See: Tag... 82 .23 5.83 L838 5 52.8 _§§ 832.2. 32 5.. 8.3.22... 28.28 am... 28.8 20.8.. 48.8% .82 5.8“ rag? 03.2 92.2 2....2 22.8 3.89 82 2.8 83.88..” - «2.2 08.2 .268 84.85 52 a o u o a m a... .30 .9... .3... 9.0 .c. .3. s... .8 2...... .8 8.... =8 .3 .80 .8 2.... .8 .oz 32 - 52 . “.2258 8.2.02 s 8:56:86 82$ 32:. 8.8.62: 3 camp 74 4.2.7 Amortization As noted above, the capital project expenditures of all the study communities were standardized by amortizing the actual capital spending that had occurred during the study period. The amortization was for 30 years period at a fixed 5% interest rate. This approach was selected for several reasons. First, it showed the underlying production cost of services without confusing them with how local governments might have decided to finance them (Schmid, 1997). Second, each year’s capital project spending is distributed into the future, mostly 30 years, through bond issuance and similar means. Although actual cash disbursement in full amount of the project cost might have taken place during one fiscal period of a local government, assigning the total amount of that disbursement to that particular year’s expenditure will be overstatement. Analogously, it will be under statement of the expenditures of the subsequent years. Third, the total expenditures of the study period will not be affected by expenditures prior to 1981 because debt service expenses were netted out. The amortization process is depicted in Tables 4.8 and 4.9 below. For example, if the 1981 Meridian Township capital project expenditure of $99,472 is amortized for 30 years at 5% interest rate, there will be equal annual payments of $6,471 each year for 30 years before inflation adjustment. The capital project expenditures entered for each of the fifteen years were the horizontal sums of the amortized and adjusted capital project expenditure in Table 4.7. For example, the 1994 capital project expenditure of Meridian Township is $483,762. This is the sum of all the annual capital project payments from 1981 to 1994. But, in 1994 Meridian Township had incurred an actual spending of 75 Table 4.7: Adjusted and Amortized Total Expenditures of Meridian Township Adjusted Adjusted Amortized Year 0p Exp. CP Exp. Op Exp. CP Exp. 1981 3,668,436 99.472 6,165,439 1982 4,321,659 236,613 6,848,905 1983 4,421,958 97,717 6,751,081 1984 4,823,647 1.873.457 7,021,320 196. 1985 5,415,421 316.631 7,563,437 211 771 1986 5,712,405 377,991 7,729,912 237. 1987 5,855,134 43.447 7,643,778 238.67 1988 6,145,325 35,976 7,691,270 , 230.9 1989 6.855.610 30,536 8.239.916 226.17 1990 7,604,565 1.242.594 8,771,125 311 2 1991 8.837.046 1.477.270 9.851.779 414 1 1992 9,793,884 440,707 10,622,434 445 1993 0.052.948 83,216 10,626,795 441 71 1994 9,710,919 835,579 10,011,257 483 78 1995 9,827,968 605,378 9,827,968 507 17 $835,579 (see Tables 4.4, 4.5, 4.7, and 4.8). Out of this $835,579, it is only the amortized and adjusted value of $56,211 that entered as part of the 1994 capital project expenditures (see Table 4.9). The amortized balance of this $835,579 actual spending (excepting the payment of $54,356 in 1995) will be carried into future periods that are outside the time range of this study. The grand total expenditures of all the study communities was computed by summing the total operating and capital project expenditures reported in Table 4.7 after completing all the netting out of the total operating expenditures, amortizing the capital project expenditures, and adjusting both expenditures for inflation. Each year’s grand total expenditures were divided by the corresponding total population to obtain the total per capita public services expenditures (see Table 4.10) 76 .88 38.8 23 88.8 88.8 88.8 83 2.3 8...« 88.8 :88 :32 :8... «8.2 :3 88.8.. 38. 38.8 23 88.8 8.8 8.8 83 83 83 88.8 :88 :32 :8... «8.2 :3 3.8.. .8. 23 88.8 88.8 88.8 83 83 83 88.8 :88 :32 :8... «8.2 :3 2«.8 82 88.8 88.8 83.8 83 83 83 88.8 :88 :32 :83 «8.2 :3 8:24 «8. 88.8 88.8 83 83 83 88.8 :88 :32 :83 «8.2 :3 °:«.::.... .8. 88.8 83 2.3 83 838 :88 :32 :8... «8.2 :3 88.28.. 82 83 83 83 88.8 :88 :32 :8... «8.2 :3 83.8 82 23 83 88.8 :88 :32 :83 «8.2 :3 88.8 82 83 838 :88 :32 :83 «8.2 :3 :38 :8. 88.8 :88 :32 :83 «8.2 :3 .8.::m 82 :88 :32 :8... «8.2 :3 .838 82 :32 :8... «8.2 :3 8.2.... 82 :8... «8.2 :3 ::.:.. 82 «8.2 :3 238 «8. :3 «:38 .8. m8. 8. 82 «8. .8. 82 82 82 :8. 82 82 82 82 «8. .8. .38. ..> 82 . .8. .888. 8.82. .o 8.2.888. 8.2.... 2.80 8.82 8.. 882.. ed 298. 77 .88 38...... 23 88.8 83.8 8.8 83 2.3 83 83.8 :88 :32 :83 «8.2 :3 2.8... 38. .83... 833 :88 38.8 .88 83 83 83 818 83.: 83.8. :3 :83. «83 «8.8. .8. 8:3 838 8832 38.8 ««..« 83 83 .88 38.8 .88. 8:3 3.3. 283 2:2... 82 «8.8 83.8. «8.8 :..« 83 83 83.8 :38 «2.8. :83 «83. «8.: 8.2... «8. :32 38.8 8.3 83 83 .88 8.8 :88. 2.3 .83. 8...: 8...... .8. :88 8..« «:3 8.3 .88 8.8 88.8. 83 :83. ....: ::«...m 82 2«.« 23 8.3 3:...:« 23.8 8.8. «2.: 8..:. 8«.: 8.38 82 83 383 388 8:8 33... 8...: 8:.:. 8...: 8838 82 83 838 238 38.8. 83.: 833. 8:.: 83.8« :8. 288 38.8 «83... 8:.: 8:3. «:3 838 82 83.8 832 :8.: :83. 833 ::...« 82 :.332 83 :28 3:3 .28. 82 833 838 3:3 :28 82 3:88 23 8:8 «8. «83 «83 .8. 82 8. m8. «8. .8. 82 82 82 :8. 82 82 82 82 «8. .8. .38. .2 82 - .8. 3.38%. 8.83.2 .o 8.2.888. .83.. .880 8.8.2 8.. 38.55 ad 333. 78 Table 4.10 Per Capita Public Service Expenditures of Meridian Township Grand Total Total Exp. Year Exp. Population Per Capita (a) (b) (0) (NC) 1981 6,174,291 29,443 210 1982 6,878,691 30,132 228 1983 6,789,215 30,821 220 1984 7,217,774 31,510 229 1985 7,775,209 32,199 241 1986 7,967,475 32,888 242 1987 7,882,456 33,577 235 1988 7,922,196 34,266 231 1989 8,466,094 34,955 242 1990 9,082,402 35,644 255 1991 10,265,929 35,770 287 1992 11,068,368 35,896 308 1993 11,068,507 36,022 307 1994 10,495,019 36,148 290 1995 10,335,147 36,274 285 4.2.8 State Equalized Value of Properties The flfieen years state equalized value of properties in the forty-six local governments were collected directly from the report of State Tax Commission, Department of Treasury. Following the same procedure of inflation adjustment, all of the equalized values were adjusted by the capital expenditure deflators. The section labeled “other” includes properties listed under Timber-Cut-over Real Property, Developmental Real Property, and Personal Property. The first two real properties are seldom available in all the communities and were very insignificant. They were added with Personal Property and labeled “Other” just to account for 100% equalized property value in a community. 79 89 . 62 6233.500 x8. 085 ”8.58 8.82.88 08.88 08.88.88 838.8 88.5.3 82.8.2 82 838.8 88.8.8 03.8.88 «8.8.88 8«.8«.5« 83.8.— 82 282.888 8.88.8 838.88 «8.288 2.3.2.888 «8.8.8.— 82 88.88.88 838.2. 8«.2«.«8 §.8o.« «3.88.8. «8.88 82 «8.25.8 «8.28.8 28.388 88.83 28.82.82 «8.«: 82 2a8q8« 88.8.8.2. 8.88.88 88.828 «888.82 «8.88 82 $85.88 28.82:. 2882.82. 28.38.. 2.2.3.82 38.83 82 5.838 2888.8 «88.8.. 08.83 888.5 «8.82 82 2.83.88 5.88.; «88qu 28.8: 88.5.8. 88.22.. 82 8m.8«.§ 28.3.8 8.88.3.8 838.2 2888.8. 832.. 82 28.288: 88.808 828.88 «8.85 8.22.22 88.83 82 8.5.8.. «8.28.8 8880.3 238.2 828.5 88.28.. 82 8«.8«.§ 88.8.8 82.2.8.8,” 88.8.88 «8.8.22 88.28.— 82 88.82.82. 888.8 2.8.88.8” 88.52 838.2. 8m.«8.. 82 8888.5 «8.82.8 «2.838 .883 «8.2.8.3 88.28.. 82 .53 8.832 .25 8:83. 288. 32928 32.3.2 .; 82 - 82 .9883 8582 .8282“. .0 28> .8838 22m “:..« 032. 4.2.9 Population Density Population density was one of the significant variables in the empirical analysis of this study. The yearly population densities were calculated by dividing the total population by the land area of the communities. Table 4.12 shows the changes in annual pepulation density of Meridian Township as an example while Table 4.13 displays the total land area of each local government in the study,. Similar population density tables were prepared for all the study communities. Table 4.12: Total Land Area and Population Density of Meridian Township 80 Land Area Density Year (sq. mile) (persons/Sq. Mile) 1981 33 892 1982 33 913 1983 33 934 1984 33 955 1985 33 976 1986 33 997 1987 33 1,017 1988 33 1,038 1989 33 1,059 1990 33 1,080 1991 33 1,084 1992 33 1,088 1993 33 1,092 1994 33 1.095 1995 33 1,099 81 .82 .8889 .25... 2. .3 3:8 228.3 E £8.55 .882 .882 528.5 8.38 e... 8953 E .82 8.8.5 282 e... 8...... saw .0 .5588 E .858 e Q 8&5 8 Q as: 532 3 E 5% .80 e E s_ 2 Q 2385 8 Q .855 8 E 9.3 as: 8 E 588:: 8 E 8.2.22 8 Q 9.3 88; 8 E 852 8 8 E km 8.3 R Q .98; 8 8 E 22.5 8 3:25 8 8 E «88 8 E 28%: 8 8 Q .85; 8 E 282.: 8 Q max .2858 8 E 28.8 3 Q 2%: 8 8 E 28m 2.20 8 E 2%: 8 c Q .88; 8 E £28m: 8 c Q 858: 8 E 23.286 8 . 8 E 232 8 E 8.2.58 8 Q as: 88.2.... 8 E .2 0888 8 E 2.8 8 8 E582. 8 E88 8 «pa $2 m2< 23 28:20:86 23 26:30:26. 23 59:32 .o 38w 9: 5 9.8.5900 moo.— uc§20 «mm...— ofi _o «02 2.3 ”n 3 03m... 82 4.3 The Empirical Method of Analysis The data set used in this study is interchangeably called panel, longitudinal, or crossfsection time-series data. Fifieen years of observations on cross-section of forty-six local governments, a total of 690 observations, were made available. There were sixty- nine local governments that qualify as fast growing communities according to the definition adopted for this particular study. Forty-six local governments representing difl‘erent population sizes, geographic location, and government types were selected as samples. Two major inferences were drawn from earlier studies that relate to this research. The first one was that variations in public service expenditures across communities can not be fully explained by an analysis of a historical data for a single variable of observation (a local government in this case) over a certain period of time only. This suggested that a ' time-series analysis that uses a set of observation drawn fiom one observational variable at a number of points in time should not be used alone. Secondly, an observation of a single year data of many observational variables did not help to produce consensus on factors explaining the variations in public service expenditures. Consequently, cross-section analysis that uses a sample of a number of observational variables all drawn at the same point in time should not be used alone. Therefore, panel data, that comprises both cross- sectional and time-series data, was collected and organized and a corresponding panel data analysis technique that combines the above two methods of analysis in a single econometric equation was employed. 83 4.3.1 The Fixed Eflects Econometric Model The econometric model used to analyze this data set is called the Fixed Efi’ects model. Indeed, there is one other model, the Random Effects model, that could have been considered as an alternative to the use of Fixed Effects model. But, because (a) the random effects model presupposes the existence of an overall intercept for all units of observation (local governments), and (b) it assumes that the random error associated with each cross-section unit is uncorrelated with other or missing regressors, it is not applicable for this particular study. For instance, if public service expenditures per capita is regressed on total number of population, and that demography (which is actually a missing variable in this particular study) can affect the intercept, then, running the regression with random efi'ect model will create correlation between the error term and population, because population and demography are likely to be correlated. The fixed effect modeL however, avoids these sorts of problems and produces results conditional on the units in the data set only (Greene, 1997). Moreover, while Random Effects model is suitable for a small sample data drawn from a larger population at random, Fixed Effects is usually used for a data set that exhausts the population (Kennedy, 1992). In the case of this study, the sample data set used exhausts the population in that it consists of all the cities (100%) and twenty-nine of the fifty-two townships (56%). Therefore, the choice and use of the Fixed Effects model was justified. 84 4.3.2 Assumptions of the Fixed Effects Regression The use and application of the Fixed Eflects regression technique in this study are based on the three basic assumptions of the model: heterogeneity, stochastic relationship, and residuals. 4.3.2.1 Heterogeneity of Units of Observations. Heterogeneity across the observation units in the context of this study was considered to be essential. It was based on the assumption that the constant term, a), of the regression equation (model) vary across the local governments and the time periods and the differences across units can be captured in differences in the term. 4.3.2.2 Stochastic Relationship Preliminary observation of the expenditure data set showed that the relationship between the public service expenditures and the explanatory/independent variables were not fixed, exact, or detemiinistic. Since the study was conducted under a non-experimental and uncontrolled environment, it was necessary to assume that the relationship between the explanatory variables and the dependent variable (the per capita public service expenditures) are stochastic in nature. 85 4.3.2.3 The Residuals This is a critical assumption in that it is based on the assertion that the relationship between the dependent and the independent variables of the model is significantly influenced by the disturbance or error terms (commonly called residuals). In other words, the estimation of the unknown or and [3 parameters of the independent variables largely depends on the nature of the error terms. Error terms could arise in this study from one or combinations of the following factors. First, several variables (like demography and politics, for instance) that may have systematic and/or irregular influences on public service expenditures were not included in the model. This omission could constitute specification error that leads to inaccurate estimation of the economic relationship between public service expenditures and the independent variables. Second, because of data collection difficulties and the inherent measurement problems in some of the variables, measurement errors could be committed. For example, the figures used for density were more or less approximation. That is, besides dividing the total population by the total land area of the local governments, the exact measure of density for the communities was not available. Third, people decided public service expenditures. Usually, people randomly make difi‘erent decisions under identical circumstances that can not be explained or measured with identifiable variable. The Fixed Effects regression technique, by taking all these assumptions into consideration, performs a complex statistical analysis that controls these and similar error terms and yield more reliable empirical results. 86 4.3.3 Mathematical Representation of the Fixed Effects Model The basic framework of the Fixed Eflects model utilized here to describe the average relationships between the dependent and the independent variables was as developed by William Gould (1997) and Greene (1997): yr: = a+fln +vr +5.1 (1) where: ya. = dependent variable (per capita public service expenditures of unit iat time t) x5. = vector of all independent (explanatory) variables (of unit i at time t) a = constant (intercept) B = estimated coefficients of the independent variable v = unit-specific residual (differs between i units but constant for any particular unit) a = “usual” residual (with mean 0, uncorrelated with itself, uncorrelated with v, and homoscedastic) From equation (1) it follows that y, = a+f,.,6+v,. +5, where: j", , f, , and e.- are averages of y... x... and a... In other words, they are within-group means. Subtracting equation (2) from (1), we obtain y. - Y.- = (x. - 37.- W + (8.. - a. (3) Equation (3) is the most common form of the Fixed Eflects estimator. But, in this ' formula, (1 remains unestimated. Therefore, with fiirther mathematical manipulation, it follows from equation (1) that 87 j) = Sifl + V + 5 (4) where j", 52, V , and t? are the grand averages of y", x", v, and 5.. The computation of the grand averages follows the formula, 9 = {(ZZym N} i=l l=l where N = number of observations Summing equations (3) and (4), we obtain yrr“yr+.9=a+(xrr—f+£)fl+(£rr-Er+v)+é (5) Then, the Fixed Effects regression estimates the above equation under the constraint v = 0. That means, it estimates y“ -7,. +5) = a+(x,., -f+x),6+noise 3; 3 It should be noted that adding in grand means to the left and right hand sides of the equation has no effect on the estimated 8. CHAPTER FIVE DETERMINANTS OF PER CAPIT A PUBLIC SERVICE EXPENDITURES IN FAST GROWING COMMUNITIES OF MICHIGAN 5.1 Introduction This chapter presents results of the statistical analysis of the variables described in previous chapters and the empirical output of the Fixed Effects regression model developed in Chapter Four. Descriptive statistics of the selected variables are discussed in detail. Methods used for data classifications are presented and the diagnostic regression performed to check for existence of any statistical problem in the model is explained. The final regression results of the model are displayed in their respective categories and, finally, the result of the reliability test of the model is shown. 5.2 The Variables Although all of the forty six local governments selected for this study are generally classified as fast growing communities, they are very diverse in their population size, population growth rate, population density, land use characteristics, and level of total expenditures per resident. They range from Sparta Township in Kent County, which spent only $34 per person (in 1981) to City of Auburn Hills, Oakland County that 88 89 spends $1,029 (in 1995). A general summary of the selected explanatory variables of the communities is presented in Table 5.1. Table 5.1: Minimum. Maximum, and Mean Values of Selected Variables, 1981 - 1995. Variable Mean Minimum Maximum Expenditure Per Capita 287 34 1,029 Total Population 28,745 4,038 119,929 Population Growth Rate 0.018 -0.01 0.06 Population Density 1.086 112 3383 Agricultural Property 281 O 2.259 Commercial Property 3,542 392 12,177 Industrial Property 1,602 0 12,335 Personal Property 2,254 351 10,731 Residential Property 11,879 5,107 34,706 Business Property 7,399 789 25,945 Total Property 19,558 8,558 58,331 Total Land Area 28 3 57 5.2.1 Population The annual population growth rate fi'om 1981 - 1995 for most of the communities is about 2% on average. However, there are a few cases where population increases and decreases have deviated from the general pattern of steady growth. For example, the 1994 projected population data for Cascade Township, Kent County, indicated a decline of population to 12,352 in 1994 from 12,896 in 1990. This has resulted in a projected 1% decline in annual population growth rate of the township between 1991 and 1995. On the other hand, there are some places that have shown sharp increase much above the average 90 for all communities between 1981 and 1990. Macomb Township, for example, had a growth rate of 4 to 6 percent each year during the period. Table 5.2: Average Total Population of the Seventeen Fast Growing Cities in Michigan, 1981 - 1995. City Avegqe Population Counties Sterling Htsw 115,590 Oakland Troy 72,686 Oakland Farmington Hills 71,133 Oakland Wyoming 63,157 Kent Rochester Hills 57,569 Oakland Portage 49,303 Kalamazoo Kentwood 36,127 Kent Novi 31,277 Oakland Holland 24,336 Ottawa Auburn Hills 17,085 Oakland Walker 17,011 Kent Grandvillei 14,992 Ottawa Wixom 8,311 Oakland Marysville- 8,259 St. Clair Lapeer 7,534 Lapeer Walled Lake 5,942 Oakland Brightonl 5,452 Livingston , The population distribution in the study communities ranged fiom 4,038 in Long Lake Township in 1981 to 119,929 in the City of Sterling Heights in 1995 with a grand mean of 28,745 (Long Lake Township had a population of 5,977 in 1990 to be included in the study). Most of the communities with the largest population are cities and townships in Southeast Michigan. Four of the first five cities in Table 5.2 (Sterling Heights, Troy, Farmington Hills, and Rochester Hills) with the highest average population for the study period are cities in Southeast Michigan. Likewise, there is no fast growing township outside of Southeast Michigan that has a population of 50,000 or more or is in the group 91 of the first five townships with the highest average population during the study period. In general, fast growing big cities and townships in Michigan are concentrated around the City of Detroit, in Southeast Michigan. Table 5.3: Average Total Population of the Sampled Fast Growing Townships in Michigan, 1981 - 1995. Township Average Population Counties Clinton 83,597 Oakland Waterford 67,262 Oakland Canton 55,762 Wayne W. Bloomfield 51,711 Oakland Shelby 46,535 Macomb Meridian 33,703 lngharn Georgetown 30,660 Ottawa Commerce 26,726 Oakland Delta 25,882 Clinton Harrison 24,741 Macomb Plaintield 24,358 Kent Chesterfield 24,164 Macomb Orion 24,143 Oakland Macomb 20,733 Macomb Delhi 19,032 lngham Holland 17,047 Ottawa Pittsfield 16,717 Washtenaw Northville 16,466 Wayne Muskegon 15,096 Muskegon Cascade 11,941 Kent Milford 11,879 Oakland Fruitport 11,382 Muskegon Grand Rapid 10,313 Kent Garfield 10,178 Grand Traverse Alpine - 9,686 Kent Sparta 8,047 Kent East Bay 7,835 Grand Traverse Long Lake 5,560 Grand Traverse Ira 5,369 St Clair 92 5.2.2 Equalized Value of Properties1 The distribution of per capita state equalized values of properties (“properties” henceforth) in these communities has some identifiable patterns. All cities and townships combined, the residential properties range from $5,107 to $34,706 and business properties2 range from $789 to $25,945. Overall, the mean value of residential property in the entire study communities is more than that of business property by nearly $4,500. Many of the seventeen cities, with the exception of the cities of Portage, Novi, Holland, and Lapeer, do not have agricultural land at all. Even in these four cities, the per capita value of agricultural properties is insignificant when compared to those of other types of properties. In the case of townships, however, all the twenty-four townships in the study have some agricultural properties. Those townships that do not have agricultural properties are Clinton, Harrison, and West Bloomfield townships in Southeast Michigan and Cascade and Grand Rapids in Kent County (outside of Southeast Michigan). In sum, agricultural property is the type of property with the lowest mean, minimum, and maximum per capita value in all the study communities. Its contribution to the per capita value of total properties is insignificant; it is just a little more than 1 percent of the total properties. All cities and townships, excepting Long Lake Township in Grand Traverse County, have both commercial and industrial properties. Long Lake Township did not have industrial properties from 1981 - 1991. The value of its commercial properties for the ' Unless stated otherwise, all references to difi‘erent types of properties must be understood in terms of per capita state equalized values (PCSEV). 2 It should be noted that business properties are expressed in terms of per capita value and not a per business value. 93 period between 1981 - 1995 was also not significant; it ranged between $392 - $574 in comparison to the $3,542 mean for all places. Four of the five communities (Table 5.4) with the highest average value of business properties (Wixom, Troy, Auburn His, and Novi) are cities located in Southeast Michigan. But, five of the communities with the highest average value of residential properties consist of three townships (W. Bloomfield, Cascade, and Northville) and two cities (F armington His and Troy). However, still four of the five communities, with the exception of Cascade Township again, are located in Southeast Michigan". It is worth noting that (1) Cascade Township, with a combined business and residential per capita value of $41,006, tops all communities included in the study, and (2) most of the communities that have the highest average value of residential properties are townships. 3 Average values of business properties are the sum of average PCSEV of industrial, commercial, and personal properties. Table 5.4 (a): Table 5.4 (b): 94 Average PCSEV of Business Properties, Cities, 1981 - 1995 City Business Properties Wixom 22,161 Troy 18,966 Auburn Hills 13,793 Novi 13,572 Marysville 13,289 Brighton 11,515 Walker 11,390 Kentwood 11,350 Farmington Hills 10,012 Wyomigg 8,653 Portage 7,969 Lapeer 7,700 Sterling Hts 7,178 Grandville 6,773 Walled Lake 6,058 Rochester Hills 5,767 Holland 5,345 Average PCSEV of Residential Properties, Cities, 1981 - 1995 City Residential Properties Farmington Hills 17,366 Troy 17,166 Rochester Hills 16,557 Novi 14,460 Sterling Hts 12,069 Marysville 11,240 Brighton 10,731 Grandville 10,304 Walled Lake 9,550 Holland 9,144 Kentwood 9,058 Walker 8,874 Portage 8,770 Wyoming 8,061 Wixom 7,835 Auburn Hills 5,907 Lapeer 5,605 95 Table 5.4 (c): Average PCSEV of Business Properties, Townships, 1981 - 1995 Township Business Properties Cascade 15,719 Garfield 12,296 Pittsfield 12,071 Delta 10,597 Holland 8,858 Milford 7,596 Chesterfield 6,093 Meridian 5,639 Grand Rapid 5,553 Commerce 5,504 Orion 5,365 Waterford 4,941 Shelby 4,896 Alpine 4,755 Ira 4,532 Plainfield 4,331 Canton 4,173 East Bay 4,099 Northville 3,956 Muskegon 3,741 Sparta 3,732 Harrison 3,608 Clinton 3,573 W. Bloomfield 3,314 Delhi 2,772 aorgetown 2.509 Macomb 2,260 Fruitport 1,446 LongLake 925 96 Table 5.4 (d): Average PCSEV of Residential Properties, Townships, 1981 - 1995 Township Residential Properties W. Bloomfield 26,440 Cascade 25,287 Northville 17,827 Grand Rapid 16,191 LMe 16,094 Commerce 15,496 Milford 14,379 Shelby 13,789 East Bay 13,685 Meridian 13,527 Orion 13,327 Macomb 13,027 Harrison 12,736 Delta 11,822 Georgetown 1 1,613 Waterford 1 1,539 Canton 11,356 Clinton 10,973 Plainfield 10,581 Chesterfield 10,535 Garfield 9,357 Fruitport 9,051 Delhi 8,785 Holland 8,684 Pittsfield 8,284 Alpine 8,152 Ira 7,612 Sparta 7,359 Muskewn 6,236 97 5.2.3 Total Land Area and Population Density The average land area for all the communities in the study is 28 square miles. It varies from the smallest area of 3 square miles, Walled Lake City, to 57 square miles, Orion Township, both in Southeast Michigan. The average density over the 15 years period is 1,086 persons per square mile and ranges from 112 persons per mile in Long Lake Township in 1981 to 3,383 persons per square mile in Clinton Township in 1995. Generally, most of the communities with the highest population density are cities. While thirteen of the seventeen cities in the study have a population density of 1,000 or more only seven of the twenty nine townships have a population density that is comparable to the cities. Furthermore, excepting for the cities of Wyoming, Holland, Kentwood, and Portage, nine of the thirteen cities are located in Southeast Michigan(see Table 5.5b). Similarly, with the exception of Meridian Township (Ingham County) all of the six townships in this category are also in Southeast Michigan (see Table 5.5a). Generally, most of the populated communities are currently located in Southeast Michigan. Table 5.5(a): Townships with Average Population Density (persons per sq. mile) of1,000 or More,1981-1995 Township Density Location Clinton 2,986 SEM Waterford 2,156 SEM Harrison 2,019 SEM W. Bloomfield 1,981 SEM Canton 1,549 SEM Shelby 1,330 SEM Meridian 1,021 ROS Note: In Tables 5.5a and 5. 5b SEM stands for Southeast Michigan and ROS for Rest of the State. 98 Table 5.5(b): Cities with Average Population Density of 1,000 or More, 1981 - 1995 City Density Location Sterling Hts 3,211 SEM Wyoming 2,429 ROS Farmington Hills 2,156 SEM Troy 2,019 SEM Walled Lake 1,981 SEM Holland 1,868 ROS Rochester Hills 1,599 SEM Kentwood 1,571 ROS Marysville 1,376 SEM Brighton 1,363 SEM Portage 1,297 ROS Lapeer 1,256 SEM Novi 1,009 SEM 5.2.4 Per Capita Public Service Expenditures The mean per capita public service expenditures for all communities combined over the fifteen year period is $287 and individual community mean expenditure range fi'om $34 to $1,029 in constant 1995 dollars. There is a clear pattern of expenditures in relation to type of government and geographic location of communities. Over all, cities spend more per person than townships, and communities located in Southeast Michigan (cities or townships) spend more than those in the rest of the state. However, as an exception to this observation, out of the twenty-nine townships of the study communities, three townships in Southeast Michigan (Shelby, Clinton, and Waterford) have spent a little more than three cities (Rochester Hills, Kentwood, and Grandville). 99 Inter city comparison reveals that cities in Southeast Michigan spend more than cities in the rest of the state. It is only the City of Holland in Kent County, outside of Southeast Michigan, that is among the top ten cities with the highest per capita expenditures. For townships, they are only Delta, Meridian, and Muskegon townships, outside of Southeast Michigan, that are among the top ten with the highest expenditures. The association between total population size and expenditures is not conclusive when all communities are combined. This is because there is no clear pattern of association between population and expenditures for cities. Nonetheless, it is observed that smaller population size cities spend more than larger population size cities on the average. For example, seven of the ten cities with the highest expenditures are from the smaller population size group (see Table 5.6). In the case of townships, however, there is a general trend of positive association between per capita public service expenditures and total population size. The larger the population size, the higher the expenditures (see Table 5.7). Table 5.6: 100 Average Expenditures and Population, Cities, 1981 - 1995 Cities Expenditure Population Lapeer 791 7,534 Marysville 636 8,259 Auburn Hills 618 17,085 Holland 604 24,336 Brighton 569 5,452 Wixom 514 8,311 Walled Lake 514 5,942 Troy 503 72,686 Sterling Hts 457 115,590 Farmington Hills 450 71,133 Novi 449 31,277 Walker 440 17,011 Wyoming 376 63,157 Portage 335 49,303 Grandville 317 14,992 Rochester Hills 292 57 .569 Kentwood 285 36,127 Table 5.7: 101 Average Expenditures and Population, Townships, 1981 ~1995 Township Expenditure Population Shelby 325 46,535 Clinton 307 83,597 Waterford 296 67,262 Canton 275 55,762 Delta 262 25,882 W. Bloomfield 257 51,711 Meridian 254 33,703 Pittsfield 233 16,717 Harrison 225 24,741 Muskegoi 206 15,096 Northville 198 16,466 Cascade 192 11,941 Holland 183 17,047 Commerce 176 26,726 Delhi 164 19,032 Chesterfield 141 24,164 Garfield 139 10,178 Orion 137 24,143 Grand Rapid 128 10,313 Milford 119 11,879 Plainfield 111 24,358 Macomb 102 20,733 Georgetwon 102 30,660 Fruitport 101 11,382 East Bay 100 7,835 Ira 92 5,369 Alpine 91 9,686 Long Lake 68 5,560 Sparta 52 8,047 102 5.3 Data Classification Preliminary review of the study data indicates that the local governments in the study sample are very different in many respects. For instance, cities and townships have substantial difi‘erences in services they provide and expenditures they incur; local governments in Southeast Michigan have expenditures that are significantly higher than those of municipalities and townships in the rest of the state; and townships with a larger total population size have higher per capita expenditures than townships with a smaller population size. These differences in patterns and levels of expenditures call for classification of the study communities into some homogeneous or uniform sub-groups of communities in order to carry out a meaningful empirical investigation. This analyst contends that ignoring these observable differences and performing a general empirical analysis by putting all the study communities in one group may make the results flawed and less important for firture use. 5.3.1 Classification by Type of Government As noted earlier, cities and townships are very different in their service responsibilities and financing authority. For example, cities have to provide for the construction and maintenance of roads and streets in their jurisdictions. Townships, to the contrary, are not required to provide road services; they are served by county road commissions. Consequently, road and street expenditure, which is very significant in terms of annual financial outlay of a community, creates significant difference between a city and 103 township budgets. Because townships do not have this huge expenditure, their budget appears to be significantly lower than those of city budgets. Furthermore, cities in the study provide their own police and fire protection, whereas townships could contract such services from a neighboring jurisdiction, county, or the state. While all the cities have their own police and fire departments, by 1995 there were only ten of the twenty-nine townships (Canton, W. Bloomfield, Shelby, Waterford, Pittsfield, Clinton, Meridian, Chesterfield, Grand Rapids, and Ira) that had their own public safety departments. The remaining nineteen townships were contracting the services fi'om the adjoining city or county departments. This also contributes to the disparity between city and township budgets and expenditures. Therefore, it is necessary to separate the communities by their respective type of governments (city or township) first and foremost. It is possible to investigate the impact of type of government on expenditures of communities by specifying it as one of the independent variables in the regression analysis using other econometric techniques like the Ordinary Least Square (OLS). But, since this study is using a Fixed Eflects regression model of panel data type of government can not be used as an explanatory variable because it remains as a constant within the panel throughout the fifteen years period of the study. Because it does not change year by year (a community is a city or a township throughout the period) it can only be represented by dummy variables 0 or 1 in the model. Since individual level covariates are not compatible with the Fixed Eflects regression model, the variable will automatically be dropped fi'om 104 the regression analysis if included‘. Therefore, the opportunity of regressing expenditures (dependent variable) on type of government (independent variable) without using other regression model is not available in this study. A single factor analysis of variance (ANOVA) is performed to test the appropriateness of separating the study communities by types of government. The result obtained (see Table 5.8) shows the existence of significant difference between cities and townships and the classification is justified. The associated two-sample t-test, which indicates the source of the differences also gave a t-statisticss of 26.7 at 0.05 confidence level with a P-value of 0. Table 5.8: Single Factor ANOVA, by Type of Government Type of Average Gov’t Count Expenditure Variance F value P-value Cities 255 475 28594 Townships 435 174 7351 Between Groups 964 0 ‘ A Fixed Eflects regression was performed with location as an independent variable to illustrate how such variables that remain constant in the panel will be treated by the model. While its inclusion does not affect the regression result, the variable will just be dropped (see Appendix F). Same result would have been obtained if similar regression was performed with type of government variable. 5 All t-statistics in this study are at 0.05 confidence level and critical value of 1.96 105 5.3.2 Sub-Classification by Population Size and Geographic Location The study communities are further sub-classified by population size and geographic locations. Cities and townships are respectively sub-grouped into two population sizes (large and small) and two general geographic locations (Southeast Michigan and Rest of the State). These sub-classifications are necessitated because the preliminary review of the data indicated that population size and geographic location are significant in shaping the level and patterns of expenditures of the communities. The determination of the two population size groups (more than 50,000 and less than 50,000) is arbitrary. The broad locational sub-categorization is confirmed by the test and result of a Single Factor ANOVA and a two-sample t-test assuming unequal variances yielding a t- statistics of 10 and 0 P-value. Table 5.9: Single Factor ANOVA, by Geographic Location Average Location Count Expendihrres Variance F value Povalue Southeast Michigan 360 351 42826 Rest of State 330 214 19802 Between Groups 101 0 6 The average expenditure indicated here is computed before disaggregating the communities into their respective types of government. 106 5.4 Characteristics of the Study Communities by Sub-Classification This sub-section will present the descriptive statistics of all the study communities arranged by the major classification of type of government and the sub-classifications of population size and geographic location. To firrther highlight the differences between the communities of different sub-class, two summary tables, one for cities and one for townships, will be presented. 5.4.1 Cities The seventeen fast growing cities of Michigan included in this study are characterized by average expenditures of $479, total population of 35,633, population growth rate of 2%, population density of 1,547 per square mile and total property value of $21,478. While only six of the seventeen cities have larger population size (more than 50,000) in 1990, four of them are located in Southeast Michigan. Moreover, eleven of all the fast growing cities (65%) are again in Southeast Michigan. 5.4.1.1 Cities of Larger Population Size The six cities in this population size group are Sterling Heights, Troy, Farmington Hills, Wyoming, Rochester Hills, and Portage. On the average, this group spends about $402, which is $77 less than all cities combined. Consistent with the average population growth rate for all fast growing cities, this group has average population of 71,573 with nearly 2% annual growth rate. The average per capita value of its total properties is 107 $23,084 and it is slightly over the average for all cities by $1,607. Its population density is much higher (by 573 persons per square mile) than the average for all cities. 5.4.1.2 Cities of Smaller Population Size Cities of Kentwood, Holland, Novi, Auburn Hills, Walker, Grandville, Wixom, Marysville, Lapeer, Walled Lake, and Brighton make this group. The group spends $522 per person on the average (that is $120 more than cities with larger population size) and $43 more than the average of all cities combined. The average population is 16,030 and the growth rate is more or less consistent with all cities combined. The value of its average total properties is less than that of larger cities by nearly $2,500. Its population density is significantly less than that of the larger cities by 884 persons per square mile. 5.4.1.3 Cities in Southeast Michigan The fast growing cities in Southeast Michigan are Sterling Heights, Troy, Farmington Hills, Rochester Hills, Novi, Auburn Hills, Wixom, Marysville, Lapeer, Walled Lake, and Brighton. The average expenditure of this group $527, which is $48 more than that of all cities combined. Its average total population size is a little more than the average of all cities combined (by 807), while its average annual population growth rate (2.2%) is significantly higher than all other categories. It has the highest average per capita value of total properties and slightly higher population density than the average for all cities. , 108 5.4.1.4 Cities in the Rest of the State. The fast growing cities outside of southeast Michigan are Wyoming, Portage, Kentwood, Holland, Walker, and Grandville. This group spends $134 less per person than cities in Southeast IVflchigan. Its average total population is less than the average for all cities combined by 1,478 and for larger cities by 2,285. Its annual population growth rate (1.5%) is the slowest when compared to all sub-classes of communities. It also has the lowest average value of properties ($3,853 less than that of all cities combined) and population density only higher than the communities with smaller population. Table 5.10: Summary of Basic Characteristics of Fast Growing Cities in Michigan 1981 - 1995 Variables Small SE Rest of Sale All 402 522 527 393 479 Total 71 1 440 34 155 Grth . Rate 1.9 2.0 2.2 1.5 2.0 119 1 1 13 1 425 1 Value 17 21 478 5.4.2 Townships Out of the total fifty-two fast growing townships in Michigan twenty-nine (56%) are included in this study. While fourteen of these townships are in Southeast Michigan the other fifteen are in the rest of the state. On the average, this sample group is characterized by per capita expenditure of $174 (which is $305 per person less than that for the cities), 109 population of 24,707, population growth rate of 1.8%, population density of 816 persons per square mile (almost half of the cities) and per capita property value of $18,432 (nearly $3,000 less than the average of the cities). There are only three townships in the entire group of the fast growing townships in Michigan that have a population size greater than 50,000 by 1990 and all three of them are located in Southeast Michigan. 5.4.2.1 Townships of Larger Population Size The three townships in Southeast Michigan that make the large population size group are Waterford, Clinton, and W. Bloomfield. This group has an average expenditure of $287, which is more than the average for all townships combined by $104. Its average population size is 67,523 and its annual growth rate of 1.6% is close to the average of all the townships combined. The population density in this group is very high, 2,193 persons per square mile and is almost three times that of all the townships. Its average per capita value of properties exceeds that of all townships combined by $1,800. 5.4.2.2 Townships of Smaller Population Size Twenty-six of the twenty-nine sample townships are in this group. These townships spend $161 per person, significantly less (by $126) than the townships with larger population size. The average population size is 19,768 and the annual population growth rate is equal to that of the average for all townships (1.8%). It has a low population density of 658 persons per square mile. This is less than a third of that of the “0 larger population size townships. The average per capita value of its properties is also less than that of larger townships by $2,057. 5.4.2.3 Townships in Southeast Michigan The fourteen sample townships in southeast Michigan are Clinton, Waterford, W. Bloomfield, Commerce, Orion, and Milford in Oakland County; Shelby, Harrison, Chesterfield, and Macomb in Macomb County; Canton and Northville in Wayne County; Pittsfield in Washtenaw County; and Ira in St. Claire County. Their average per capita expenditure ($206) is more than the average for all townships by $32. The group average population is about 34,000 with an average annual growth rate of nearly 2%, higher than the population growth rate for all townships combined. The average per capita property value and population density are also greater than those for all townships combined. 5.4.2.4 Townships in the Rest of the State Townships in the rest of the state are Plainfield, Cascade, and Grand Rapids in Kent County; Meridian and Delhi in Ingham County; Holland and Georgetown in Ottawa County; Delta in Clinton county; Muskegon and Fruitport in Muskegon County; and Garfield, East Bay, and Long Lake in Grand Traverse County. These townships spend $62 less per person than townships in Southeast Michigan. Their average population (16,048), annual grth rate (1.6%), per capita total property value ($17,966), and population Ill density (511 persons per square mile) are also considerably less than those of Southeast Michigan. Table 5.11: Summay of Basic Characteristics of Fast Growing Townships in Michigan. 1981 -1995 Variables Small SE Rest of aate 287 161 206 144 Total 67 19 768 986 1 Growth . Rate 1.6 1.8 2 0 1.6 193 658 51 1 Value 20 1 17 112 5.5 Regressions and Model Specification This study uses a fifteen-year panel data set utilizing the Fixed Effects regression method. The amount of data used in this study is so large that it was necessary to be concerned about the existence of possible statistical problems in the model. For example, there could be a significant change in the regression coefficients if one adds or omits an independent variable in the process of model specification. As a result, the estimated standard errors of the fitted coefficients would be inflated, or the estimated coefficients of the explanatory variables may not be statistically significant even though a statistical relation exists between the dependent and independent variables. Therefore, before embarking on the actual regression analysis a diagnostic regression is performed on all data sets. The diagnostic regression employed is primarily focused on the problem of correlation between the independent variables and the test showed the existence of multicollinearity problem in the initial model of the study. 5.5.1 Diagnostic Regression One of the frequent problems observed in several studies like this one is when the explanatory (independent) variables are highly correlated (multicollinearity). Two of the independent variables (square of total population and total land area) that were initially included in the model specification are detected by the diagnostic regression to have caused such a problem in the regression analysis of this study. 113 Square of total population was included in the model for the purpose of adjusting for the non-linearity that may exist between total population and expenditures. Total land area was included because many of the prior researchers have used it. Even some of them, Shapiro (1961) for example, had found it to be the most significant variable in explaining the expenditures of local governments. Variance of Inflation Factor (vif) analysis is utilized following the diagnostic regression in order to measure the degree of multicollinearity between the independent variables and to calculate the level of tolerance for each of the variables in the model. Most analysts rely on informal rules of thumb applied to the vif (Chatterjee and Price, 1991). Some use the vif value of 30 and others use the more restrictive value of 10. The diagnostic linear regressions and the corresponding vg'f values of this study are presented below in Tables 5.12 A - 5.14 B 5.5.1.1 Results of Diagnostic Regression for all Communities When all communities are considered together, the maximum vrf values for the total population and population density in the diagnostic linear regression that incorporates both square of population and land area are 28.7 and 14.14 respectively (Table 12 A). This is mostly because of the high correlation between these two variables and the square of population (0.95 and 0.8 respectively, see Appendix B). When square of population is removed from the model, the vif value of total population improved significantly (by 47%) and its t-statistics (which indicates its explanatory significance) doubled (jumped fiom -2.32 to -4.83, see Table 12 B). However, the change in vrf value 114 and t-statistics of population density is not significant. This indicates that although the correlation between square of population and population density is very high, the impact of this variable on the explanatory significance of population density is insignificant. The dramatic change in the vif vale and t-statistics of population density comes when the total land area is removed fiom the model; vff improves by 78% and t-statistics changes from 10.61 to 27. 10. As expected, since population density is calculated from total population and land area, the result reveals that the explanatory significance of population density is much affected by total land area. The removal of both variables from the model improves the mean and individual vrf values of all variables without any impact on the explanatory ability of the model. Furthermore, results of the diagnostic regression indicate that significance of square of population as an explanatory variable in the model is very low. It has a t-statistics of -1.7 or less at 0.05 confidence level confirming that its contribution in explaining the variations in expenditure of the study communities is insignificant. In summary, when the two variables are removed from the model, three remarkable results are observed: (1) the mean and individual vif values of all variables in the model declined significantly and fall in the range of the acceptable threshold ; (2) the t- statistics of all of the independent variables improved; and (3) the adjusted R2 of the model did not decline because of a loss of the variables. These results confirm that square of population and land area are not useful variables in the model. Table 5.12 (A): Results of Diagnostic Regressions, Cities and Townships Variance Inflation Factor Wrth Land Area Wrthout Land Area Variables Wrth Pop? Wrthout PopZ Wrth PopZ Wrthout Pop2 Total Pop. 28.70 15.30 11.50 3.26 Pop. Density 14.14 13.92 3.17 3.12 Sq. of Pop. 10.61 ~- 10.16 --- Pop. Gr. Rate 1.03 1.03 1.03 1.03 Resid. Prop. 2.71 2.70 2.53 2.48 Total Property 2.53 2.53 2.37 2.36 Land Area 5.83 5.58 -—-- -—- Mean VlF 9.36 6.84 5.13 2.45 Table 5.12: (B) The t-statislics the Diagnostic Regressions, Cities and Townships t-statistics Mth Land Area Wrthout Land Area Variables Wrth PopZ lMthout PopZ Wrth PopZ Wrthout PopZ Total Pop. 232 -4.83 -7.24 -15.47 Pop. Density 10.29 10.58 27.10 27.14 Sq. of Pop. -1.77 --- -1.19 --- Pop. Gr. Rate 2.47 2.54 2.46 2.51 Resid. Prop. 46.75 -16.64 -18.05 -18.05 Total Property 21.56 21.51 22.91 22.87 Land Area -2.96 ~2.65 ~— - Adjusted R2 0.70 0.70 0.70 0.70 5.5.1.2 Results of Diagnostic Regression for Cities The individual and combined impacts of square of population and land areas become more clear when the communities are classified by types of government. Inclusion or omission of these variables in the model have dramatic impacts for cities. Total 116 population, as an explanatory variable for expenditure patterns of cities, would be rendered useless if the two variables are included in the model. The vg'f value of 117.89 (Table 5.13 A) is very far from the tolerance threshold of even the most generous cutting point of 30. There would be a serious multicollinearity problem that will drop all the contributions of population variable in the analysis. Just removing square of population will bring down the vif near the 30-point threshold indicating that the multicollinearity problem in the model is significantly reduced. Although the magnitude is not the same, the vrfvalues of all the remaining explanatory variables have improved or have remained the same. However, unlike in the case of all communities combined, removing the square of population from the model reduced the explanatory significance of all the variables (excepting that of population grth rate, which is not significant in the model anyway) and reduced the explanatory ability fiom 44% to 43% (see Table 5.13. B). This trend is reversed when land area is removed. The W] values of all variables improved significantly (with only population and its square being in excess of the 10 points threshold). Leaving the explanatory ability of the model at 43%, the explanatory significance of all the variables (with a small exception of population grth rate again) improved dramatically. The omission of both variables assures near complete absence of any multicollinearity problem in the analysis. All variables have vg’f value of less than 3.1 and the mean drops to 2.49 from 27.79. Again with the small exception of population growth rate, the significance of all explanatory variables improves substantially. However, the model’s ability to explain the variations in expenditures of cities declines by 4%. Table 5.13 (A): 117 Results of Diagnostic Regressions, Cities Table 5.13: Variance Inflation Factor Wrth Land Area Wrthout Land Area Variables Wrth PopZ Wrthout Pop? Wrth PopZ Wrthout Pop2 Total Pop. 117.89 30.09 12.05 2.24 Pop. Density 16.61 12.48 3.40 2.86 Sq. of Pop. 26.04 --- 13..15 --- Pop. Gr. Rate 1.28 1.28 1.27 1.26 Resid. Prop. 3.49 3.48 3.20 3.05 Total Proper 2.66 2.58 2.29 3.04 Land Area 26.58 13.43 -- --- Mean VIF 27.79 10.56 5.89 2.49 (B) The t-statistics of the Diagnostic Regressions, Cities t-statistics Wrth Land Area Wrthout Land Area Variables Wrth Pop2 Wrthout Pop? Wrth Popz Wrthout Popl Total Pop. -1.67 0.25 -7.99 903 Pop. Density 2.16 1.29 6.62 8.66 Sq. of Pop. 2.08 -—- 3.85 --- Pop. Gr. Rate 0.89 0.90 0.80 0.44 Resid. Prop. 399 -3.86 4.45 -5.28 Total Propery 7.64 7.34 8.61 9.01 Land Area 093 335 ~— ~— R2 0.44 0.43 0.43 0.40 118 5.5.1.3 Results of Diagnostic Regression for Townships The impacts of the two variables in the case of townships is considerably different from that of cities. Indeed, removal of population square or land area or both improves the vrfvalues of all the variables (Table 14. A). However, the t-statistics of all variables (excepting population grth rate) decline with a removal of any of the variables. Likewise, the explanatory ability of the model declines by 5%. Although there is no strong case in itself for removing square of population and land area fi'om the model for townships, because there is no variable with a vif value that is significantly greater than the liberal 30 points threshold of tolerance, the need to use uniform analysis for both cities and townships in this study necessitate the omission of these variables. Table 5.14 (A): Results of Diagnostic Regressions, Townships Variance Inflation Factor Wrth Land Area Wrthout Land Area Variables Wrth PopZ Wrthout Pop2 Wrth Pop2 lMthout PopZ Total Pop. 30.78 21.03 16.14 6.91 Pop. Density 22.79 22.55 7.57 7.23 Sq. of Pop. 13.41 --- 13.41 --—- Pop. Gr. Rate 1.07 1.05 1.07 1.05 Resid. Prop. 5.00 4.89 4.91 4.79 Total Property 4.71 4.68 4.67 4.63 Land Area 3.21 3.21 -- --- Mean VIF 11.57 9.57 7.96 4.92 Table 514(8): 119 The t-statistics of the Diagnostic Regressions, Townships t-statistics Wrth Land Area Wrthout Land Area Variables Wrth Popz Wrthout Pop? Wrth Pop2 Wrthout Popz Total Pop. 10.36 6.70 9.14 4.93 Pop. Density 1.14 0.30 9.00 7.12 Sq. of P0p. 789 ~- -7.56 ———- Pop. Gr. Rate -1.58 -2.63 -1.33 -2.37 Resid. Prop. 955 -7.91 -10.05 -8.45 Total Property 15.54 13.97 15.66 14.17 Land Area -5.14 -4.65 ~- -- R2 0.77 0.74 0.76 0.72 120 5.5.2 Fixed Eflects Regression Fixed Efl’ects regressions are performed for each sub-class of cities and townships with the five explanatory variables (as developed in chapter three) using equation 5 in chapter four: M: ‘y:' -.Y" = a +(xrr ' x! - Jl“9.3+ (a. - 8.’+ v') + e" The preliminary regression analysis of the data indicated that while industrial, commercial, and personal properties have positive association with expenditures, residential and agricultural properties, as expected, show negative association. Because the share of agricultural properties in the study communities is very small and its ability to explain variations in expenditures of communities is insignificant, it is decided not to treat it as a different variables from the rest. Residential property, however, has to be treated as a separate variable because of its large share in total property and very significant explanatory power in the model. 121 5.5.2.1 Regression Results? The regression results presented in Tables 5.15 for cities and 5.16 for townships show: (1) the expenditures of the two classes of analysis (cities and townships) are afi'ected differently by each of the explanatory variables; (2) the different sub-groups within the same class of analysis have different sets of ranking of the independent variables in accordance with their contributions in explaining the variations in expenditures of their respective sub-groups; (3) while almost all variables are significant in explaining the variations in the expenditures of cities (last column of Table 5.15), it is only the total property variable in the model that is significant for townships (last column of Table 5.16); (4) the regression model does a better job in explaining the variations in expenditures of townships than cities. 5.5.2.2 Regression Results for Cities The regression model explains 68% of the variations in expenditures of all fast growing cities in Michigan. Total property, followed by residential property, is the most significant variable with the highest explanatory power. While both population growth rate 7 It should be noted that the values that are used for total property and residential property are. different. While per capita value is used for total property, proportion of residential property as percentage of total property is used for the later. Therefore, the interpretation of the coefiicients of the two variables are different. Take the regression result for cities as an example: The (3 value for total property is 0.17. That means, a 1% change in per capita value of total property is followed by $0.17 change in per capita total expenditure. In the case of residential property, the coefficient of - 734.8 is stating that if the proportion of residential property as a percentage of total property changes by 1%, the per capita total expenditure will change by $7.35. 122 and density have some statistical relation with expenditures, total population is the third significant variable in the model that explains the variations in expenditures of cities. The empirical finding fiom the regression analysis of all cities combined does not support the hypothesis of a positive correlation between population size and expenditures. The hypothesis developed in chapter three states that the higher the population size, the higher the expenditures will be. This statement does not make any distinction between government types, city or township. Table 5.15: Fixed Effects Regression Results, Cities Large Small SE Michigan Rest of State All Variable Coeii t stat 0081. t stat Coat. t stat Coei. t stat 00811. t stat Total Population 001 -1.8 -0.02 -4.0 -0.01 -4.7 0.00 0.2 -0.01 -4.8 Pop Growth Rate -103 0.3 2003 2.7 1407 2.0 2.5 0.0 953.7 1.8 Residential Property -169 -1.4 -621 -5.5 -753 -6.7 -326 -1.1 -735 -7.8 Total Property 0.01 7.7 0.02 10.6 0.02 9.5 0.01 5.2 0.17 11.1 Population Density 0.51 1.9 0.02 0.3 0.14 2.0 -0.09 -0.4 0.122 2.0 Constant 221 2.0 533 7.6 679 8.3 409 1.7 659.3 9.5 R2 0.77 0.74 0.72 0.54 0.68 Total population, excepting in the case of the six cities outside of Southeast Michigan, is negatively correlated with expenditures of all classes of cities. These six cities outside of Southeast Michigan are Grandville, Walker, Holland, Kentwood, Portage, and Wyoming. Scatter diagrams, showing the trend of correlation between average population and expenditures over the fifteen years period, for all classes of cities are presented. Cities outside of Southeast Michigan indicates the positive association between population and expenditures while all classes of cities show negative (see Chart 5.2). 123 Public service expenditures are driven not only by the quality and quantity of services provided, but also by the infrastructures and agencies that make the services possible. Overhead expenditures for running and maintaining the service infi'astructures are part of fixed costs in the public service production function of local governments. Total average cost of producing and maintaining certain units of public services will be relatively higher in those communities that have smaller population size because there are fewer people among whom the expenditures could be distributed. Furthermore, if the service boundaries of a local government are greater than its political boundaries, its expenditures will be overstated because the effective population served is greater than the population by which the expenditures is computed. For instance, Schmid reports that the City of Lapeer extends its fire protection service to adjoining townships. This will increase Lapeer’s fire protection expenditures figure. If the computation of the per capita fire protection expenditures does not count the actual number of population served and it is only divided by those who consider Lapeer as a place of their abode, the expenditures of Lapeer is bound to be overstated. Similarly, if all residents of a political jurisdiction are not served, but the computation of the per capita expenditures of that service does not exclude those not served, the expenditures of that community is bound to be understated. In general, disparity between effective population that gets the service and the population by which the per capita is computed could cause misrepresentation of the expenditures figures and change the sign of association. 124 Chart 5.1 Average Population and Expenditures, all Cities, 1981 - 1995 800 w. 700 ... 600 +. O o 500 ~~ o o o o o g 400 -~ . o 300 r . 200 - ~ 1 00 . - 50.000 100.000 150.000 Population Chart 5.2 Average Population and Expenditures of Cities Outside of Southeast Michigan, 1981 ~1995 TN 60041 O 8500) O 4004 . fiscal o .0 “32(1)“ 100» 20.000 40,000 60,000 80,000 Population 125 Chart 5.3 Average Population and Expenditures of Cities in Southeast Michigan, 1981 ~1995 20,00 40,00 60,00 80,00 100,0 120,0 0 0 0 0 00 00 Population W .'§§§§§§§s O O 00 0 Chart 5.4 Average Population and Expenditures, Large Cities, 1981 - 1995 Expendituea 888888 0 O 0 AL A I 7 20,000 40,000 60.000 00,111.30 100.00 120,“) 0 0 Population 126 Chart 5.5 Average Population and Expenditures of Cities with Smaller Population size, 1981 - 1995 eoo~—¢ 300. 0 O Q 80 . 400‘ ° 0 O . 200‘» - 100) 20,00 30,00 40,00 50,!” 0 0 0 0 0 Population It is generally observed from the descriptive statistics that smaller cities are associated with higher per capita expenditures and the larger cities with lower expenditures. This inverse relationship between population size and level of expenditures is captured by the regression results as well. In cases of both larger and smaller population size groups, signs of the estimated [3 coefficients and the t-statistics are negative. This confirms the association of high population with lower expenditures and low population with higher expenditures. Five of the six cities that show negative association between total population and expenditures belong to the smaller population size group. Then, why do the cities outside of Southeast Michigan, that are predominantly in the smaller size group, show positive correlation between size of population and expenditures? Indeed, these cities as a group spend less than cities in Southeast Michigan. But, does this positive correlation indicate that expenditures increase as a result of secular growth of population, as stated in the hypothesis, or are there diseconomies of scale that result from sheer increase of residents 127 to be served? Unambiguous answers for this question may not be drawn fiom the data at hand. Thus, this analyst proposes firrther inquiry in this area. Although population density shows positive association with expenditures of all cities combined, the variable is found to be inconclusive when all the sub-classes of cities are treated separately. Population growth rate, however, not supporting the hypothesis that it will have an inverse relationship with expenditures, shows a positive statistical relationship. this suggests that the rate at which residents of a community is increasing has a direct efi‘ect on changes in services provided, thereby causing increase in expenditures. The independent variable with the highest explanatory ability at all levels of classification of the cities is the per capita value of total property. The regression results support the hypothesis that total property and expenditures are positively associated while residential property and expenditures are inversely related. This finding is a confirmation of the hypothesis that total property, as a proxy of real wealth and income, enables residents to demand and pay for more and improved public services. The finding regarding residential property is consistent with the explanation of the hypothesis in chapter three in that the estimated inverse relationship between residential property and expenditures is evidence that expenditures may not need to rise as residential development increases. New residential development may not require significant financial outlays for new public services because of the existing economies of scale in some of the infrastructures and the types of its service requirements. In fact, the data shows that most of the cities and townships with high value of residential properties have very low per capita expenditures. A significant portion of total property consists of business properties (commercial, industrial, and personal). Business developments will affect public service expenditures in 128 two ways. The first one is through the expanded tax base they create for a community. More government revenue will be generated from new business developments and can be used for more or improved public services. The second is that new business activities may require new services and infrastructures that may duplicate the already existing ones thereby causing increase in expenditures. Both scenarios contribute to the positive association between total property and expenditures. With a clear exception of total property, which invariably is the most significant variable for all classes of cities, the degree of impact of each variable on expenditures of communities vary significantly. Population density, for example, is the second most important variable in explaining the expenditures of larger cities while it is actually the least significant variable in the case of smaller cities. See Table 5.15 for details. The overall regression estimate, which is the estimated per capita public service expenditures equation for all cities combined, can be represented as: Y, = 659.3 - (.01)xI + (953.7)x2 - (734.8)X3 + (0.016)x. + (0.12)x,' where Y;, = Expenditure X) = Total Population X2 = Population Growth Rate X3 = Residential Property as % of Total Property X4 = Total Property X5 = Population Density or = Constant (659.3) ' Similar per capita public service expenditures equation for cities with large and small population size and in Southeast Michigan and the rest of the state can be obtained from Table 5.14 129 Table 5.16: Ranking of Independent Variables by Level of Significance, Cities Large Small SE MMan Rest of State All Total Total Total Total Totd Property Property Property Property Prope Population Total Total Population Total Residential Density Population Population Prope Told Residential Residential Population Total Population Property Property Density Population Residentid Population Population Residential Population Property Growth Rate Density Property Densi Population Population Population Population Population Growth Rate Density Growth Rate Growth Rate Growth Rate Although it was not possible to include geographic location in the model as an independent variable, a multiple regression that treats each year’s observation as an independent record was used to just see how expenditures of communities would be afl‘ected by location. It was found that it was statistically significant with estimated 0 value of 90. 26. This indicates that if the variable was to be used in the model, it would contribute a value of 90.26 to the or constant in the estimated expenditure equation of fast growing cities in Southeast Michigan. The same analysis was done for townships and it was found to be statistically significant with (3 value of Of -10.67. This would reduce the or constant of the estimated expenditure equation of fast growing townships in Southeast Michigan by 10.67 130 5.5.2.3 Regression Results for Townships The regression model does a better job in explaining the variations in expenditures of fast growing townships in Michigan than for cities. It has an adjusted R2 of 0.72 for all townships combined, which is 4% more than that of the cities. This comparison is more obvious when it is done between the sub-groups of both cities and townships. For instance, the adjusted R25 of townships with larger population size, townships in Southeast Michigan, and townships in the rest of the state are greater than the R’s of cities of similar categories by 15, 6, and 17 percent respectively. Nonetheless, it should be noted that this model performs slightly better (by 5%) in explaining the expenditures of smaller population size cities than townships with comparable population size. Total property is very significant in explaining the variations in expenditures of townships. (1) It is the only statistically significant variable in explaining variations in the expenditures of townships when all the twenty-nine townships are grouped together. (2) It is the variable with the highest contribution to the R2 regardless of the class of townships. All of the other variables are not significant when all the townships are combined. This is indicated by their respective t-statistics (see Table 5.17). However, this observation changes when the townships are classified by a broad geographic location. The significance of almost all variables improves when townships are classified by location. Classification by population size, however, did not improve the statistical significance of the variables. 131 Table 5.17: Fixed Effects Regression Results, Townships La e Small SE Michigan Rest of State All Varlable Coefi t stat 00811 t stat Coefi t stat Coeff t stat 00811 t stat Total Population 002 -1.6 0.00 1.1 0.01 2.7 «0.03 -3.9 0.002 0.9 Pop. Growth Rate -15 «0.0 96 0.7 -193 -1.2 369 1.9 56.5 0.4 Residential Property -77 -0.4 -35 -0.8 134 2.3 -117 -1.7 -28.1 -0.7 Total Property 0.01 4.8 0.01 14.9 0.00 8.3 0.01 10.9 0.006 17.4 Population Density 0.63 2.1 0.09 1.1 -0.01 -0.1 1.1 4.3 0.093 1.3 Constant 26 0.1 -31 -1.0 -178 -3.9 9 0.2 -38.04 -1.2 R2 0.92 0.69 0.78 0.71 0.72 The regression results displayed in Table 5.17 support most of the hypothesis: total population, population grth rate, and total property show positive association with expenditures; residential property confirms the inverse relationship. Total population, which is negatively related to expenditures of all cities combined, has positive association with expenditures of all townships. This positive association may be explained by the fact that many townships are not required to have all types of service facilities, but can contract fi'om others. The services purchased from other units of government and fees paid for the service may be proportional to the number of people served. Or, the townships may decide to acquire new service facilities in response to new demand arising from growing population. In general, economies and diseconomies of scale of service facilities may not play a role to force an inverse relationship between population and expenditures. An inverse relationship between population size and expenditures is obtained in communities with larger population size and those outside of Southeast Michigan when townships are broken down into different classes. Those in smaller population size and the rest of the state show positive association and are consistent with all the communities I32 combined. The general trends of the relationship between population and expenditures of difi'erent classes of townships are shown with the help of the charts below. Chart 5.6 Average Population and Expenditures of all Townships, 1981 - 1995 350 e “‘1’ . . . 2504 ’0 0 ’0 200« e". 1500 . 10043 0°. 504°. - 20,000 40,000 60,000 80.000 100.000 Populdion Chart 5.7 Average Population and Expenditures of Townships in Southeast Michigan, 1981 - 1995 350 300 250 .. . 200 0 O 150 100 50 20.1” 40,00 60,00 800) 100.0 0 0 0 0 00 Population Chart 5.6 133 Average Population and Expenditures of Townships Outside of Southeast Michigan, 1981 - 1995 Chart 5.9 300 250 gay. i... 100.. 50 ° 0 0.. e 8 0.0 ° 0 .0 10.000 20.000 30.000 40.000 Population Average Population and Expenditures of Townships with Large Population Size, 1981 -1995 310 ‘ 300 1r 0 290 280 <- O 270 260 O 250 4 20,1!) 40$” 60,11) 80,00 100,0 0 0 0 Population 0 Chart 5.10 Table 5.18: 134 Average Population and Expenditures of Townships with Small Population Size, 1981 -1995 350 0 3m 4 250 . .0 e 200 . ‘ . 150 .. 9 . 100 .. :9} e 0 e 50 .. e 10.00 20,00 30,00 40,00 50,00 0 0 o o 0 Population Ranking of Independent Variables by Level of Significance, Townships La_rge Small SE Michigan Rest of State All Total Total Total Total Told Property Property Property Property Property Population Total Total Population Population Population Density Population Density Density Total Population Residential Total Totd Population Density Property Population Population Residential Residential Population Population Residential Property Property Growth Rate Growth Rate Property Population Population Population Residential Population Growth Rate Growth Rate Density Property Growth Rate The independent variable that had the highest explanatory ability in the model at all levels of classification of the townships was the per capita value of total property. Variables that were least important in the model varied by class of townships: (1) population growth rate was the least significant for all townships grouped together and classified by population size, and (2) population density and residential property were the least important variables for townships classified by location. Finally, there was no 135 observable pattern of ranking of the rest of the variables for the second, third, and fourth places in accordance to their contribution to the R2. The estimated per capita public service expenditures equation for all townships grouped together can be represented as: Y,. = -38 + (.002)X, + (56.5))(2 - (28.1)X3 + (0.05)X4 + (0.09)X5 5.6 Comparison of Regression Results by Type of Government Cities and townships are basically different in many respects. On average, cities spend $301 per person more than the townships; have 10,000 or more residents than townships; have population density of almost double that of townships; and have about $3,000 more in per capita state equalized value of total properties, $5,500 more in business property, and $2,500 less in residential property. While total property and rate of population growth variables were the highest and the least in terms of statistical significance in their contributions to the R2 for both aggregated classes of communities, the ranking of residential property, total population, and population density vary by classification. Moreover, total population plays different roles in determination of city and township expenditures. It was observed that increase in population size decreases expenditures for cities while it increases expenditures of townships. 136 Table 5.19: Comparison of Ranking of Independent Variables, by Types of Government Cities T Total Total Residential Total Total Residential Growth Rate Growth Rate 68 R2 72 Further observation into the regression results of both class of communities revealed that almost all independent variables, excepting total property, were statistically significant for cities but not for townships. Yet, the R2 for cities was less than that of townships. This finding suggests that more explanatory variables in addition to the ones used in the model are needed to find the unexplained factors that determine city expenditures. On the other hand, the relatively higher R2 of townships suggests that total property, with little contribution from the other variables, is the single most important variable in shaping expenditures in townships. The significance of this variable is further observed when townships are sub-divided by population sizes. Townships with larger p0pulation size have an R2 of 0 .92 with only total property having a significant value of t-statistics. The importance of total property in determining the expenditures of townships becomes more marked with smaller population size where it is the only significant explanatory variable with t-statistics of 14.9. 137 5.7 Impact of Location on Expenditures It should be remembered that location was not treated as independent variable in the model because (1) individual level covariates can not be used in a fixed effects model, and (2) it will be dropped grom the regression results if entered because it is a constant within the panel (see Appendix F). Therefore, for a purpose of showing the significance of location on expenditures, a multiple regression of the Generalized Linear Model was performed using dummy variables (1 for Southeast Michigan, 0 for the Rest of the State). It was found to be statistically significant for both cities and townships with 8 values of 90.3 for cities and -10.7 for townships (see Appendix E). 138 5.8 Reliability Test of the Model Ten cities out of seventeen and twenty four townships out of the twenty nine were arbitrarily and randomly selected to test the validity of the estimated equation of the model. The 1995 data on expenditures and the independent variables were selected purposefully for the validity test because all expenditure and property data were all in constant 1995 dollars. The estimated equations used for cities and townships were respectively: Y5. = 659.3 - (.01)X1 + (953.7)X2 - (734.8)X3 + (0.016)X4 + (0.12)X5 and Y,. = -38 + (.002)X1 + (56.5)X2 - (28.1)X3 + (0.05)X4 + (0.09)X5 where: Y5, = Expenditure X1 = Total Population X2 = Population Grth Rate X3 = Residential Property as % of Total Property X. = Total Property X5 = Population Density or = Constant Over all, for adjusted R25 of the model (0.68 for cities and 0.72 for townships), the reliability test showed that the equations have estimated the variations of expenditures within the bound of 32% under or over the actual expenditures for cities and 28% for townships. Excepting in the case of the cities of Wyoming and Walled Lake (two out of ten) and townships of Fruitport, Alpine, and Ira (three out of twenty four), the ability of the equations in estimating expenditures was very impressive. In sum, given the length of time considered in the study and the nature of the data, this validity test has shown the strength and accuracy of the model (see Tables 5.19 & 5.20). Table 5.20: 139 Results of the Reliability Test, Cities, 1995 Actual Estimated Over/Under Cih/ Expenditure Expenditure Estimated (96) Troy 569 456 020 Wyoming 438 261 -0.40 Novi 519 627 0.21 Holland 684 449 034 Walker 530 669 0.26 Auburn Hills 974 988 0.01 Marysville 698 819 0.17 Lapeer 779 721 -0.07 Walled Lake 498 679 0.37 Brighton 665 881 0.33 Table 5.21: Results of the Reliability Test. Townships, 1995 140 Actual Estimated Over/Under Township Expenditure Expenditure Estimated (‘16) Waterford 332 373 0.12 Canton 382 334 -0.13 W. Bloomfield 340 417 0.23 Meridian 285 241 -0.15 Delta 295 207 0.3) Delhi 188 130 031 Commerce 255 253 -0.01 Chesterfield 215 202 -0.06 Macomb 171 182 0.06 Holland 236 180 —0.24 Harrison 214 270 0.26 Plainfield 193 164 -0.15 Orion 182 203 0.11 Northville 269 228 -0.16 Fruitport 110 70 -0.36 Cascade M 325 293 «0.10 Alpine 139 92 034 Grand Rapid 211 182 -0.14 Garfield 181 153 -0.16 Sparta 56 60 0.08 Milford 184 163 -0.1 1 East Bay 140 105 -0.25 Long Lake 73 72 -0.02 Ira 107 69 -0.35 CHAPTER SIX CONCLUSIONS, IMPLICATIONS AND FUTURE RESEARCH 6.1 Introduction The main objective of this study was to identify the significant factors that determine the variations in per capita public service expenditures of local governments in the State of Michigan. Public services considered in the study include general government, public safety, public works, public services, health and welfare, and recreation and culture. The impacts of selected explanatory variables (total population, population density, population growth rate, per capita state equalized value of total property, and per capita value of residential property as percent of total property) on per capita expenditures were investigated in the context of different types of government (city or township), population size groups (large or small), and geographic location (Southeast Michigan or the rest of the state). The conceptual framework of the analysis was formulated as an expenditure decision model of local governments. A rigorous method of data preparation and management for the purpose of such analysis was developed and an econometric model using Fixed Efl'ects regression was employed to analyze fifteen-year panel data sets. I41 142 6.2 Conclusions The conclusion of this study focuses on three important aspects. First, the overall empirical results are summarized. Then, findings regarding the impacts of each independent variable on per capita expenditures of communities and their explanatory power in the model are discussed. Finally, the impact'of geographic location variable is discussed separately. 6.2.1 General One of the important findings in this study was the confirmation of the existence of identifiable patterns of variations in expenditures (all reference to expenditures and property values are in per capita unless stated otherwise) of fast growing communities in the State of Michigan. On average: (1) per capita public service expenditures of fast growing communities in Michigan vary widely (between $34 and $1,029 in terms of 1995 constant dollars); (2) cities and townships categorized by different population sizes have difi‘erent expenditure patterns. While cities with smaller population size spend ($120 per person) more than cities with larger population size, townships with larger population size spend ($126 per person) more than smaller townships; (3) cities spend considerably more ($305 per person) than townships; and (4) communities located in Southeast Michigan spend more than those in the rest of the state ($143 per person for cities and $62 for townships). 143 6.2.2 The Independent Variables With exception for the total property variable, the significance of the independent variables considered in this study vary across groups of communities. Variables that are statistically significant in expenditures of cities are not for townships; or variables that are significant for cities in Southeast Michigan are not for cities in the rest of the state. Likewise, a variable that has a positive association with expenditures of cities may have an inverse relationship with expenditures of townships; and the variable that was inversely related to expenditures of townships in Southeast Michigan may be positively associated ' with expenditures of townships in the rest of the state. In sum, the ranking of the significance of the independent variables and their impacts in explaining the expenditures of local governments vary by types of government, population size, and geographic location of the communities. Therefore, results pertaining to each independent variable are discussed separately. 6.2.2.1 Total Property Value The most important factor that explained the variations in the expenditure patterns of all classes of communities was the per capita value of total property. The values of industrial and commercial properties (collectively called business properties) have positive association with expenditures. Business properties affect expenditures in two ways: (1) they create expanded tax base for communities. More tax revenues generated from these properties and business related activities make more expenditures on public services 144 possible; and (2) new developments may require new and improved public services and infiastructures that may replace or duplicate existing ones In general, the value of total property was statistically significant in the expenditure model and the value of its estimated coefiicient was very large such that any ch'ange in its value will be followed by significant change in expenditures of local governments. 6.2.2.2 Mix of Land Use Mix of land use can affect the demand and need for services. For example, residential property, as percentage of total property, was found to be inversely related with expenditures of most of the communities. That means, new residential developments may not require as much new infiestructure of public services as business developments. Accordingly, it was observed that most of the communities with high residential property value have very low expenditures (less than $200). Nevertheless, it should be noted that the regression results for townships indicated that the residential property variable and expenditures of townships in Southeast Michigan were positively associated. Although the data sets used in this study do not help to firmly determine the reasons as to why such relationship was observed, the difi‘erences between types of residential: properties in Southeast Michigan and the rest of the state could be considered as a starting point for further study. In addition to the costs of settlement congestion that characterize Southeast Michigan, the preponderance of multi-family multi- story residential properties may contribute to increasing expenditures in certain types of public services. For instance, high rise multi-family dwellings and office buildings in 145 Southeast Michigan require an aerial fire truck equipped with more sophisticated equipment which may not be needed in single family residential communities that are outside of Southeast Michigan. 6.2.2.3 Population: The population variable impacts expenditures of cities and townships difi‘erently. Expenditures in cities decrease as total population increase and expenditures increases in townships as population increase. Public service expenditures are driven not only by the quality and quantity of the flow of services, but also by the costs of the infi'astructures of the services. In addition to the day to day cost of running the services and agencies that provide the services, communities incur considerable overhead expenditures to maintain existing service infrastructures. These expenditures could be considered as fixed costs in the public service production firnction. In smaller population size cities the per capita cost of producing certain units of public services will be higher because there are fewer people among whom the fixed costs could be distributed. In the case of townships, however, increasing and discontinuous jumps in public service expenditures could be observed as a result of increase in demand for better quality and quantity of services as population increases. Most of the more populated townships produce their own public services such as police and fire protection and have higher associated expenditures compared to the less populated townships that may contract such services fi'om other units of governments like county sherifi‘ and state police or may do with whatever general level of service is provided by the county government. 146 Finally, it should be noted that this population-expenditure relationship could be misleading due to the incongruity that may exist between service and political boundaries of communities. Ifthe service boundaries are greater than the political boundaries, the expenditures of the community will be overstated because the efi'ective population served is greater than the population by which the per capita expenditures are computed. For instance, the City of Lapeer extends its fire protection service to adjoining townships. This will obviously increase Lapeer’s fire protection expenditure. However, if the computation of the per capita expenditure for the City of Lapeer does not count the actual number of people served and is only based on those who consider Lapeer as a place of their abode, . then, the expenditure will be overstated. To sum up, disparity between effective population receiving the service and the number of people by which the per capita is computed will cause over/understatement of the expenditures because data on population of service areas is not generally available. 6.2.2.4 Population Density Population density, while statistically significant for cities, was found to be not significant for townships. However, care must be taken in interpreting results of this variable. First of all, the computation of density itself has a serious problem. Dividing the total population by the total land area of a local government does not tell how the population is distributed across the landscape of the jurisdiction. Two communities with equal population size and land area may have a different distribution of settlement. One may distribute all its residents on all the land under its jurisdiction and the other may only 147 confine its residents to a certain portion of its area. These different types of population distribution will have difi‘erent impacts on expenditures in that constructing and maintaining service infrastructures over the entire land area or over a limited section will have difl‘erent service and associated expenditure requirements. Second, types of service categories for which the impact of density is being investigated do matter. Difi‘erent classes of services will be impacted difi‘erently by increasing population density. In the case of road construction and maintenance, for instance, the per capita expenditures would be expegted to decrease with increasing density of population up to a point because increased volume of trafic is not expected to offset the average cost advantage that arises from increased density. On the other hand, fire and police expenditures could rise if congestion (as a result of increasing density) sets in. Hence, the overall impact of density will be determined by the share of each service category in the expenditures of local government. In this study, population density was found to be negatively associated with expenditures of cities outside of Southeast Michigan and Townships in Southeast Michigan when communities are disaggregated by geographic location. But, it was found to have positive association when all cities and townships were aggregated in their respective types of government. A negative 8 coefficient in the former case indicates that increasing population density will decrease expenditures of local governments because economies of scales are captured in the infrastructures of the services. Most of the cities outside of Southeast Michigan, generally small in population size, have firll infiastructures and services. If these communities are able to increase their population density, it is very likely that they could reduce their expenditures. 148 All of the large townships are in Southeast Michigan and have long grown over the threshold of getting by with services provided counties. Indeed, excepting for Meridian Township, all the townships, big or small, that have their own police departments are in Southeast Michigan. Ifthese communities are able to increase their density, it is possible that they would also be able to reduce their expenditures because they would achieve economies of scale in several service categories up to a point. The finding regarding these two sub-classes of communities was in agreement with a recent study of eighteen communities in Michigan. Burchell (1997) estimated that there would be considerable savings in four major areas (land consumption, infrastructures, housing cost, and fiscal impact) if new grth were added in a greater density than the existing level. The more people along a mile of water or sewer pipeline, the lower the cost per person. The study by Burchell utilized a single year cross sectional data and was based on synthetic projections that included formulas for the costs of roads and water and sewer. But the current study used actual historical data sets of fifteen years and did not include expenditures of water and sewer for all the forty six study communities and expenditures of roads for the twenty nine townships. Therefore, the positive sign of the population density coemcient for other classes of communities should not be considered as a conflicting result because the studies were conducted with different sets of data and purpose. For instance, if water and sewer were omitted from Burchell’s study, the remaining expenditures, including those for police and fire, are for services where density is associated with congestion and greater expenditures instead of economies. The regression results indicated that cities in Southeast Michigan have statistically significant positive association between density and expenditures. It was also observed 149 that this association was positive when all cities were all grouped together. This was because eleven of the seventeen cities are in Southeast Michigan and the negative correlation for cities in the rest of the state was counterbalanced or lost because of larger aggregation of cities. Although the data set used in this study does not show congestion thresholds, the positive association between density and expenditures of these commwities could be seen fi'om a settlement congestion perspective. All the larger cities in the study groups are located in Southeast Michigan. It is possible that most of these large cities may have passed over the threshold for economies of scale and are experiencing high costs associated with congestion in some service categories. For example, the conditions of road, police, and fire services in Southeast Michigan are very different from those in the rest of the state. Frequency of calls for police protection and fire emergencies require many patrol omcers and fire fighters on duty, more police vehicles, jails, and fire trucks. All these are costs associated with congestion resulting in a positive correlation between population density and expenditures. 6.2.2.5 Population Growth Rate The population growth rate variable was found to be statistically not significant for either cities or townships when they all are grouped in their respective types of government. However, when communities were analyzed in their respective sub-groups, a closer look at the regression results of cities in Southeast Michigan and smaller population 150 size group indicated that the variable was statistically significant and the sign of the estimated coefficient of the variable was positive. The implication of the observed positive correlation between expenditures of these communities and population growth rate is that it is the rate at which the population grows that contributes to the increase in expenditures rather than the actual number of residents (since actual population size is inversely related with expenditures). This is because faster population growth will be accompanied with increasing demands for expansion of services and infiastructures. The faster the population grows, the higher the service expenditures will be. 151 6.2.3 Impact of Location The role of geographic location in driving expenditures of cities and townships was captured by the Single Factor Analysis of Variance (Table 5:9), summary statistics (Tables 5:10 & 11), and the regression results of the Generalized Linear Model presented in Appendix E. It should be remembered that location was not treated as independent variable in the model because individual level covariates can not be used in a Fixed Efi’ects model alone and all constant within the panel will be dropped from the regression results if entered (see Appendix F). Therefore, Ordinary Least Square regression was performed for the purpose of showing the significance of location on expenditures. The variable was found to be statistically significant for both cities and townships. However, it showed difl‘erent signs of correlation with the expenditures of cities and townships in Southeast Michigan. It was positive for cities and negative for townships. According to this result, controlling for all the variables in the model, location alone will make the expenditures of cities in Southeast Michigan higher than those in the rest of the state by $90 and the expenditures of townships in Southeast Michigan lower than those in the rest of the state by $11. The finding for cities was confirmed by the summary statistics of cities (see Table 5:10). The summary showed that cities in Southeast Michigan spend $134 more than those in the rest of the state. But townships in Southeast Michigan, despite the inverse relationship between expenditures and location, spend $62 more than those in the rest of the state (see Table 5:11). Why would townships in Southeast Michigan have higher expenditures when they are having cost advantage related to their location? The Fixed Ejects regression results 152 showed that total population and residential property variables in the estimated expenditures equation have positive association with expenditures of townships in Southeast Michigan. In the case of the current study, the positive (3 values of these two variables in the equation had outweighed the negative correlation of location and expenditures such that the expenditures of the townships in Southeast Michigan became higher than the expenditures of townships in the rest of the state. Analogously, because these two variables are inversely related to the expenditures of the townships in the rest of the state (see Table 5:16), their negative [3 values in the equation had made the expenditures of townships in the rest of the state less than the expenditures of townships in Southeast Michigan. In sum, the reasons why expenditures of townships in Southeast Michigan are more than the expenditures of townships in the rest of the state are better explained by variables other than location. 153 6.3 Policy Implications Many people in Michigan are concerned about population settlement patterns. The Michigan Society of Planning Oficials is currently conducting a series of studies and conferences dealing with the impacts of settlements. Two major studies by academics (Burchell, 1997; Schmid, 1997), for instance, were recently commissioned. Furthermore, there is enough evidence from news media that indicate citizens of different communities are very much concerned about the increasing costs of public services provided by their local governments. Therefore, one could cautiously conclude that both the local and state policy makers on the one hand and the citizens of different communities on the other share common concerns relating to population settlement patterns and their impacts on costs and resources in Michigan. The basic assumption of this study was that the objective behind local government expenditures is providing the best public services with minimum per capita costs. Hence, the regression estimates of the per capita public service expenditures equations that emerged fiom the analysis in Chapter 5 present the opportunity for policy makers to identify the important policy instruments that could be used to control expenditures. According to the empirical results, whether all communities were grouped only by their respective types of governments or different sub-classes of population size and geographic location, the most significant factor that emerged to explain expenditures was the per capita value of total properties as measured by the state equalized value. In the case of townships, for example, it was only this variable that was statistically significant in the model (see Table 5:16). Yet, the model did a good job of explaining 72 percent of the 154 variations in public service expenditures of the twenty-nine townships. This was a very strong finding and clearly calls for a further study. It appears that communities that have wealth to tax do so and spend the revenue. At the same time, wealthier communities demand more and higher quality services. No one would advocate becoming poor or rejecting high valued land use in order to hold down expenditures. To the contrary, communities try to attract high valued land uses. They offer reduced taxes now to get more wealth in the future. Michigan has created eleven tax-fiee Renaissance Zones (six urban, three rural, and two military bases) located throughout the State where businesses and residents pay virtually no taxes up to fifteen years. This tax waiver includes the single business tax, personal income tax, real property tax, utility users tax, state education tax, local income tax, and local personal property tax (Michigan Job Commission, 1997). Such measures are expected to attract more commercial and industrial developments that could utilize existing infi'astructures and achieve economies of scale. While an increase in tax base will increase spending, it may help to keep the tax burden of the established residents lower in the future than it might otherwise be. Therefore, the statistical significance of total property does not warrant land use regulations as policy instruments to hold down expenditures. What matters is not the level of expenditures but the ability of residents to pay for the services they demand. Most of the communities with high expenditures are the smaller cities. Almost all cities provide most of the services (excepting water and sewer in a few cases) on their own, while smaller townships do not. Because of the lumpy nature of many of the services, underutilization of the existing public service infrastructures results in high public 155 service expenditures. Consistent with the findings of Burchell (1997) and Schmid (1997), such a population-expenditure relationship implies that more people could be added to the existing smaller communities and spending per capita would decrease. A small city following a dense settlement policy has two things going for it that can reduce per capita expenditures. (1) If small cities were to grow to achieve economies of scale it need not contribute to sprawl since sprawl refers to low density development, not grth in population whether it be around a metro or non-metro area. (2) City population is negatively correlated with expenditures. This finding supports a policy to increase the number of residents of existing communities. Ifthis is to take place in smaller size communities, the savings that could be obtained from the joint impact of increased population and a dense new residential development could be substantial. Settlement, nonetheless, follows jobs. Currently most of the jobs in the State are concentrated in cities and townships of Southeast Michigan where per capita expenditures are the highest (the exception is the Grand Rapids area). The projected future job growth is also in Southeast Michigan. But, if local governments outside of Southeast Michigan could use difi‘erent policy instruments to promote job opportunities in their areas by attracting new businesses, it could mean that expenditures would drop in outstate cities (that are in a sense now too small) and Southeast Michigan cities (that are or will be too large). Growth outstate could benefit Southeast Michigan by removing some of the pressure for increased spending. Outstate regions need 'new and coordinated growth strategies that will direct businesses and settlement into their areas. But, such strategies are unlikely to materialize if growth efforts are not coordinated at regional or state levels and if Southeast Michigan can not see that it is also to their advantage. 156 6.4 Future Research This research was conducted using fifteen-year data sets that include population, expenditures of public services, and state equalized value of properties. However, it remains desirable if data on other variables like measures of congestion, quality of services, income and employment in minor civil divisions (MCDs), water/sewer expenditure, and county supplied roads were available. The paucity of these types of data sets could be considered as shortcomings of this research. The lack of measures of quality of service creates problems of quantifying the actual benefits that may arise from population grth for some communities and the actual costs of population congestion for others. In many of related studies, congestion has been identified as a variable that increases the costs of public services. On the other hand, higher population density is suggested as a variable that could reduce these costs. Then, the question becomes what level of congestion will offset the benefits of higher population density, or what level ofpopulation density brings in congestion. The major service categories in this study that are affected by these countervailing efl‘ects of congestion and population density are water and sewer systems, fire and police protections, and roads and highways. The questions posed above can be answered only if it is possible to measure quality of services at different level of population density and obtain relevant data of these service categories. Public service expenditures largely depend on the resources available in a community. Household income and place of employment of residents of a community make up the larger share of resources available for public services. But, household (family) 157 income and employment information are not available at a lower MCD (city or township) level. The census data of these variables is only available at a county level. That is not that much helpful for this type of research that focuses to the lowest level of government structure because there is no way of knowing the exact share of employment and income in the community of interest. A city or a township is only a part of a county. Expenditure data on water and sewer service areas need to be included to obtain the whole picture of expenditures of local governments. But these data are very difficult to collect. The political boundaries of communities and the service areas covered by the system are often difi‘erent. Finally, expenditure on roads and major streets is one of the problems encountered in this study. Cities provide their own construction and maintenance of roads and streets while townships are served by county road-commissions. Counties do not keep expenditure records by townships, but by road or street that may run through several townships. Thus, because it is difficult to assign the exact amount of expenditure to the share of road miles in a particular township, expenditure data for this service category is not available for townships. Collecting and adjusting most of the data mentioned here may not be an easy task. However, it may be possible to reduce the magnitude of the problem through survey and primary data collection methods if reasonable financial and technical supports are available. BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY American Farmland Trust. 1986. Density-Related Public Costs. Northampton, MA: American Farmland Trust. Batrik, Timothy J. 1992. “The Effects of State and Local Taxes on Economic Development: A Review of Recent Research”, Economic Development Quarterly. Feb., 103-11. Baumol, William J. 1963. “Urban Services: Interactions of Public and Private Decisions”, in Howard G. Schaller (ed), Public Expenditure Decisions in the Urban Community, Resources for the Future, Inc. Washington, DC Berolzheimer, Josef. 1947. "Influences Shaping Expenditures for Operation of State and Local Government: Relation of Population to Expenditure Variation", The Bulletin of the National T ax Association, Vol. XXXII, no. 6. Brazer, Harvey E. 1959. City Expenditures in the United States. Occasional paper 66, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research. . 1962. “Some Fiscal Implications of Metropolitanism” in Gutherie S. Birkhead (ed), Metropolitan Issues: Social, Governmental, and Fiscal. Syracuse University: Syracuse, NY. February. Brecht, Arnold. 1941. "Three Topics in Comparative Administration, " Public Policy: A Yearbook of the Graduate School of Public Administration, Harvard University, Cambridge. Bryce, James. 1914. The American Commonwealth, Vol. 1. New York, NY. Bunnell, Gene. 1997. “Fiscal Impact Studies as Advocacy and Story Telling”, in Journal of Planning Literature, Vol. 12, No. 2. November. Sage Publications, Inc. Burchell, Robert W. and David Listokin. 1988. The Fiscal Impact Handbook. Estimating Local Costs and Revenues of Land Development. New Brunswick, New Jersey: Rutgers University Center for Urban Policy analysis. Burchell, Robert W and Nancy Neuman. 1997. Fiscal Impacts of A lternative Land Development Patterns in Michigan. Detroit: Southeast Michigan Council of Governments. 158 159 Burchell, Robert W. 1993. Fiscal Impact Analysis And The Fiscal Impact Hierarchy: A Glimpse at the Argument. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. Chapman, Jeffrey I. (1988). “Land Use Planning and the Local Budget: A Model of Their Interrelationships”, Public Administration Review. July/August. Chaterjee, S. and B. Price. 1991. Regression Analysis by Example. 2nd ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Citizens Reaserch Council. 1975. Recent Michigan Expenditure Trends, Report No. 248, Detroit, Michigan. : 1990. State and Local Government Expenditures and Revenues in the F ifieen Most Populous States. No. 992 Revised, Detroit, Michigan. Colm, Gerald, et al. 1936. “Public Expenditures and Economic Structure in the United States,” Social Research, Vol. III. Davenport, Donald H. 1926. An Analysis of the Cost of Municipal and State Government and the Relation of Population to C ost of Government, Net Taxable Income and Full Value of Real Property in New York State. Delphendahl, Johannes. 1961. Expenditure Patterns and Services Rendered by Michigan Townships, 1945 - 1958. Doctoral Dissertation, Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI.. Department of Management and Budget, Office of the State Demographer, Michigan Information Center, 1996, April. Department of State Police, Fire Marshal Division. 1996. Michigan Fire Service Directory, 1995-96, Lansing, Michigan. Downing, Paul B. 1977. “Suburban Nongrowth Policies”, Journal of Economic Issues, 11 (2). Fabricant, Solomon 1952. The Trend of Government Activity in the United States Since 1900. National Bureau of Economic Research, New York. Fischel, William A. 1985. The Economics of Zoning Laws: A Property Rights Approach to American Land Use Controls. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Frank, James E. 1989. The Cost of Alternative Development Patterns: A Review of the Literature. Washington, DC: Urban Land Institute. Gerhard Cohn et al. 1936‘. "Public Expenditures and Economic Structure in the United States," Social Research, Vol. HI 160 Greene, William H. 1997. Econometric Analysis, 3rd Edition. Prentice Hall: Upper Saddle River, NJ Gould, William. 1997. “Interpreting the Intercept in the Fixed Effects Model”, STATA Corporation, College Station, Texas Hansen, Alvin H. and Harvey S. Perlofl‘. 1944. State and Local Finance in the National Economy. W. W. Norton and Co. Hawley, Amos H.. 1951. ”Metropolitan Population and Municipal Government Expenditures in Central Cities," Journal of Social Issues, Vol. VII Henderson, J. V. 1979. ”Theories of Group, Jurisdiction, and City Size, Current Issues in , Urban Economics, editors: Peter Mieszkowski and Mahlon Straszheim. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, Judge, George G., et. al. 1988. Introduction to the Theory and Practice of Econometrics, 2nd Edition. New York : John Wiley & sons. Kelsey, Timothy W. 1996. “The Fiscal Impacts of Alternative Land Uses: What Do Costs of Community Service Studies Really Tell Us?” Journal of Community Development Society, Vol. 27, No. 1 Kennedy, Peter. 1992. A Guide to Econometrics, 3rd Edition. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Ladd, Helen F. 1998. Local Government T ax and Land Use Policies in the United States: Understanding the Links. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing Inc. Lee, Woo Sik. 1965. ”Central City Expenditures and Metropolitan Areas", National Tax Journal. December. Masten, John T. and Kenneth E. Quindry. 1990. "A Note On City Expenditure Determinants", Land Economics. February. Michigan Department of Treasury, State Tax Commission. 1981 - 1995. Report on State Equalized Valuation. Lansing, Michigan Michigan Jobs Commission. 1998. “Michigan is Now Tax Free” (BrOchure), Lansing, Michigan Michigan Society of Planning Officials. 1995, Patterns on Land: Our Choices-Our Future, Rochester, Michigan Society of Planning Officials 161 Mills, Edwin S. 1979. “Economic analysis of urban land-use controls”, in P. Mieszkowski and M. Straszheim (eds), Current Issues in Urban Economics. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Muller, Thomas. 1975. Fiscal Impact of Land Development: A Critique of Methods and Review of Issues. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute. Oakland, H. William and William A. Testa. 1995. "Does Business Development Raise Tax,” Economic Perspectives. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, March/April. Randall, Alan. 1987. Resource Economics: An Economic Approach to Natural Resource and Environmental Policy, 2nd Ed. New York: John Wiley & Son. Rubin, Marilyn. 1990. ”Urban Enterprise Zones: do they Work? Evidence From New Jersey”, Public Budgeting and Finance. Winter Schmid, A Allen. 1997. Impact of Population Growth and Distribution on Local Government Expenditures in Michigan. Detroit : SEMCOG. .1987._Property, Power, & Public Choice: An Inquiry into Law and Economics. New York: Praeger Schmid, A Allen and J. T. Purello. 1995. The Economics of population Settlement: Cost of A lternative Growth Patterns -— An Essay and Annotated Bibliography. North Central Regional Center for Rural Development, RD 172, Iowa State University, Ames. Schmid, A. Allen. 1968. Converting Land From Rural to Urban Uses. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future. Schmandt, Henry J. and G. Ross Stephens. 1963. ”Local Government Expenditure Patterns in the United States", Land Economics. November (7). Scott, Stanley and E. L. Feder. 1957. Factors associated with Variations in Municipal Expenditure Levels. Berkeley, California: Bureau of Public Administration, University of California. Shapiro, Harvey. 1961. ”Measuring Local Government Output, A comment", National Tax Journal. Southeast Michigan Council of Governments. 1994. Patterns of Diversity and Change in Southeast Michigan. Detroit: SEMCOG Southeast Michigan Council of Governments. 1993. Regional Profile of Southeast Michigan. Detroit: SEMCOG 162 STATA Corporation. 1997. Statistics Data Management Graphics, Release 5, References College Station, Texas: STATA Press. Tischler & Associates, Inc. 1993. Fiscal Impact Analysis of Residential Development Alternatives: Lancaster County, PA. Bethesda, MD: Tischler & Associates, Inc. US Bureau of the Census, Government Finances in 1987 - 1988. Walker, Mable L. 1930. Municipal Expenditures. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press Warbach, John and Mark Wycofl‘. 1995. Growth Management Tools & Techniques. Lansing: Coastal Management Program, Michigan Department of Natural Resources. Wolkofl‘, Michael J. 1985. “Chasing a Dream: The Use of Tax Abatements to Spur Urban Economic Development”, Urban Studies, 22 Wolpert, Julian and Michael N. Danielson. 1991. "The Rural Fringe in the New Metropolis,” In Proceedings: National Rural Studies Committee, Reading, PA., May 16-17 Wycofl’, Mark, eta]. 1993 Emmet County/City of Petosky Trend Future Report. Lansing: Planning and Zoning Center, Inc. APPENDICES APPENDIX A: SUMMARY STATISTICS 163 Hmmm mm mmmmv HomHN mwmmm mo. mNmmHH mNoH Aoawa mumsvm\mc0mummv >uflmcwa umdfidum>ow Hmooq no comm coma Hmuos aunomoum Hmuos mo moam> Umuaamsvm mumum mpumaoumamwucouflwmm mo osHm> comaamsvm oumum >uummoum mmmcamsm mo o5am> nwufiamsvm mumum oumm nuzouw mmha.mmm hbmHN.NH mmm.mmv> 5mm.mmav www.mmmm vamHHo. mm.mmbom HHNm.bmH .>mo .num mmm.ova thHv.HN m.>>vam mm.mvhoa mm.mbmoa vmmmmao. ha.mmmmm mvmm.mhv muflmmo mom muflamu Mom muflmmu mom coflumHsmom :oHumHsmom Hmuoe mousuflvcmmxm oofl>uom oflansm muflamo mom coflumHsmom u uncov mecca Quaamuou auaucomu QuQmCmQ nuZHUQom Hmuoumoa ncmmxo "ouoz umcmo Hausa Qumamuou Qumucomu mummcmn nuzumaom amuoumom vcmaxm magmaum> noduwo Add AH.H2¢V 164 Hmmm mm mmmmv HomHN mvmmm mo. mNmmHH mmoa vomo.mmm mnwhh.h mma.o>mm www.mwma moa.m>mm vvmmoo. ma.bmbha mmam.oma .>mo .Uum mmw.vaH bmwma.vm Hw.vmmba N.mmom mmm.mhmm mHo. Nm.vmavm HHHm.Nmm oumum an» no puma as» an mmmb.omw mvmmm.MH mmm.vmam mvo.mmbv qvm.mmom vnmmmao. Nv.mmmmm mmmN.HhH .>ma .nom www.mama momom.ma mm.mbmmm m.ow©HH mN.mHmHH NNo. Hh.mmvwm Hmom.mmm uncov Hausa Qumamuou Qumuaomu Qummamn nuzuumom Hmuouaom vcmmxo magmaum> mmwuwu Am.H24v umcmn mecca Qumamuou Quaucnwu Quamcmn nuzummom Hmuoumoa vcomxo magmaum> savanna: uuaosusom cw uoauao .N.Hg4. 165 Hmmm mm mmmmv HomHN Hmmvm mo. mNmmHH vmm mavv.mav mommom.m mmm.mmmm www.mvmm Nob.bmvm mmvwofio. mH.meoH moH.va .>ma .uum hmo.mmma mmvmv.vH hm.Homom mvm.bmmm mm.m>HHH mmbmmfio. vm.mmowH HNHm.HNm umcoo “mesa aumamuou Qumucomu Qummcmn ADZHUQOQ Hmuoumoa ncmmxm manmfium> downwaflmom HOHHmEm gawk uafluwo Am.H2v wm>.mmom Hmmamao. mo.avomm mommv.mm mmm.mHHN bmmma.¢m mo.vmomm vm.ammma hmv.>mbm mmmmmao. ba.MhmHh boom.HO¢ uncoo owned Quaamuou Quaucvmu Qummcmn nuzuomom Hmuoumoa ocwmxm lllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +lllllllll .>ma .num mflnmflum> coauuaaaom uooumq and: uoauao .v.H:<. 166 momm.omh Hahmo.oa vmv.ammm vmm.vmmm vha.nmmm NbeHHo. Hm.vmmNN mmmva.hm .>mo .num cm0w£0fiz unmouaom a“ uawsocsoa mHHm.vmw Homvvm.m Ham.Hth bmv.vmvm mom.hm>m vaomao. Hm.mmoma mvovh.mm .>ma .num mmm.mvaa mmN¢H.Hm m.NmmmH hm.mbmma Hmm.vmam mmommao. Ha.mmmmm bmmm.mom Hmmv.wam hammo.am mv.vamH hh.mvaH Hmh.hbvm Nmmwbao. m.ronwm vbmm.mra umcmn “coca Quaamuou Quaucvmu Qummcmn cashmmom Hmuoumoa ncmmxm magmaum> AN.N.$ uncov Hausa Quaamuou Qumuccmu Quamamn nuzumaom amuouaom ocmaxm maanum> DQMSuc3OB HH(_AH.N.¢9 167 mmma.mmm mmhbmv.m www.momb mom.mmmh mmo.mMHH mmamoao. Hv.vhova memm.om .>mo .oum scandaamom kahuna gawk unfinnczoa bmvm.mvm NmvaN.m av.mvmm owm.HbNm mom.vaov «maomao. vN.Nvmm Hmmwm.mh .>ma .cum mmm.NmHN mmmmm.Hm mH.>hNON vv.>amma www.mvmm 0H0. Ha.mmmhm mmmm.mmm mbmo.HHm mMMMH.Nm vm.mmmha hv.HobHH NH.mmbm mmao. mo.mvomH NNvm.mvH umcov amend Quaamuou Quaucomu Qummcmn nu3uomoa Hmuoumoa ucmmxm manmflnm> 3&2: umGoU Mecca Quaamuou aumucomu mummCmQ nuzumaoa Hmuouaom ocoaxo magmaum> «anon on» no once as» ea nagguczoa .m.u.¢e 168 mmmm.oov momwmb.m mvo.mmm> www.mmmv mnm.vmmm hmmmmao. MH.VHHNH mpmmH.mb .>mn .num coauaaaaom uoafimem nuns nannuczoa mvmm.bmm Hmmmm.am mm.mHNmH MN.POHNH Hm.vmmm mommbao. hm.hmhma mmmw.omH uncov Mecca Qumamuou muaucomu QHQmCmQ casummom Hmuoumoa ucomxm wanmacm> .m.~.5 APPENDIX B: CORRELATION ANALYSIS OF THE VARIABLES 169 HmHN.or oooo.a vao.o Hamo.o oooo.H mmbH.o hvmo.o mem.o oooo.H Nvma.0| homo.o mnoo.o: ommo.o oooo.H ovom.o wvmo.o vmoo.ot mvHH.o mmmo.or oooo.H mmmm.o vwoa.o mome.o vaH.o mmmo.or mmmm.o oooo.H mNNh.o OOHH.OI Hmbm.o mmmm.o thH.OI mvvm.o HNNb.o oooo.H _uwcmumoa _umvcH _Qumamuou _Quaucnmu _nu3uvmom _vmmom _Hmuouaom _Uchxo IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII +IIIIIIII. Hmuoumoa vcoaxo mmam.o oooo.H Quaamuou Qumucvmu nuzumaoa uawnuc3oa .ooHQMwun> mHmN.0I moHo.o mmom.o mmNN.o oooo.H Ummoa neoocoaoocu on» no coaunaauuoo .~.m. HHNm.o Nmmm.o Hmma.o Namv.o mmvm.or oooo.H Nmmb.o Hmom.o HmHN.o vmom.o ova.0I mmvm.o oooo.a wao.0I mwmv.or mvHN.o vmo~.or moao.o thH.OI mmmN.OI oooo.a _umcooaom Cong .muaamuou _Qumucvmu _nu3uoaoa _Umaoa _HMuoqum _ocoaxm IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII +Iu.l.ll||.l.l Hmuoumoa vcwmxm momo.o mmbm.o Hmvm.o Harv.o oooo.H mmo>.o oooo.H Quaamuou Qumucvmu suzuomom Unmoa nowuao .uoHAMMun>_ucoo:oaoocH «no mo coauaaouuoo .H.m. APPENDIX C: DIAGNOSTIC REGRESSION RESULTS 170 mmmo.oom mammmom. Hammom.m mmmmwflo. mmmmroo. Hm.ommw wormmm.v thmooo. mm.hNH n mmHv.o mmmv.o oooo.o m>.>~ _ mH> cmoz llllllllllllllllllllll +lllllllll mmHHm>.o m~.H _ nuzumaoa mommpm.o mm.~ . mundane» mmmom~.o mo.m _ auaucnmu mmaomo.o Hm.wH _ umcmnaom moammo.o vo.m~ _ vmaoa mmmpmo.o mm.m~ _ umuca mmemoo.o mm.>HH _ Hmuouaom IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII +.l.ll.l.|||l.l mH>\H mH> _ manmflum> mmH.mmH ooo.o Hmv.v mvfimm.>> «amm.>¢m _ mcou mommmoo. Hmo.o va.~ «sheave. NmOmFOH. _ umcmnaoa Hmmmmm.mu ~mm.o mmm.ou «mmamm.m mmmpmfl.mu _ “mead hammmoo. ooo.o one.» pmmpaoo. mmmmmflo. _ auaamuou mmmmfimo.n ooo.o mmm.mu «Hmomoo. momaeao.t _ auaucnmu pfim.m¢mn mfim.o mmm.o mvmm.~mn mmvotmmm _ nusuoaoa moummm.H mmo.o mmo.~ moumm~.H mouovm.m _ emaoa Hmomofio.s mmo.o onw.au Hummmoo. mombvoo.u _ Hmuouaoa llllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +Illllllll .ucoo wmma _u_Am u .uum .eum .umoo _ ucmaxm mm: uoom mmmm.mmam~ «mm am.mmmmmae _ Hmuoa voumsvmrm mom IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII + IIIIIIIII umumsvmum Hamm.m¢mwfi new HH.Hmmemov _ Hmsoflmmm m A beam vom.mmam¢v n mm.mm~mfiflm _ Hmnoz Ahvm .h am It: .......... t ......... untuuua+ ..... n--- vN.bN mmm mno no no £852 m2 up mm _ condom uoauao .noanuaun> Add nuflz_.eoauuoumem oauuocmuao .H.a.o. I71 memfimb.o Novbmm.o mmormm.o mvaomo.o mmvvbo.o mmmmmo.o hH> cmmz nuzummom Qumamuou Qumucnmu umcmnmoa Hanna Hmuoumom mammammm mmmNHvH. vmmmvm.ml mbmHch. Nmmmmoo.t HHH.omNN mmmfimoo. mmom.mbN mmhvmmo.l hammm.NHI wmvmmoo. HmmNHNo.I mmma.v¢ml mhbvmoo.l whoom.0h Nfivmmvo. mmbHNv.N vmmrfioo. momwmoo. mmvo.mmh movvaoo. mwo.hH¢ mmmmo. mvmmHH.ml mathHo. Hmbovao.l mmwm.>or mmmooo. mcool umcmomoa Hanna Qumamuou mumucomu nu3ummom Hmuoumom Hr.mNH u mHHv.o bmwv.o oooo.o ¢m.om mmN mmz uoom noHMSUmtm mom boundvmrm m A noum Amvm .w who no Honfidz Cm wom¢.mwmma mvN NmH.mmmbom w llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +|llllllll m2 MU ma.mm~moa¢ mH.bmmmvom mm Hmsofimmm Hmnoz ouusom nowuuo .co«uudnmom uo Cunard u:onua3..c0duuouuom Own-ocmdda Aw.fi.uv 172 0mmmmh.0 ¢0mwmv.0 v0m~am.0 mmmmmm.0 000000.0 HN00>0.0 hH> cmmz £u3uamom mumamuou Qumucnmu uncoomom Hmuoumom Unmom mem.hmm HO0Hmma. hmmeao. mNHmmoo. www.mmam 00rflmo.m wdmvmoo. mmom.m0m vowvaH. mamboao. bv0MNN0.I Hm0N.mamt 00t0mm.a 00H0000.I mNN00.Hv mmbvwwo. 0mNmH00. mmbvmoo. mwb¢.mhh wormbm.m Hmomooo. thv.00N mommmva. mmmmmao. mmmvmao.l 000m.maw molmvm.m m¢MN>00.I mcool uncovaom Qumamuou mumucumu nusummoa vmmom Hmuoumoa wNNm.mmHON va llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +l'l'l'll' mmmm.mmmma mvm 00H.0HO0Hm w IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII +nl'lI-III'II N0.bNH mmHv.0 wmmv.0 0000.0 mw.am mmm mm: uoom nwumsvmrm nod noumsvmrm m A noum Amen .0 who no Honfidz 0m m2 we vm.wmmmmfib HN.mhmHm0v MH.HO0NOHM mm Hmsnflmom Hmuoz condom Coaudu .IOH<_UGIA unocuak..co«uuoumtm aflauocunfla AM.H.UV 173 0Nv0.HmN m00HmNN. mvamao. 0mvmaa0.l mhm.mama mbmmm00.I wvaw.~vfi Hmmmfiefi. mmmwafio. mmonN0.I mp0.HNNHI meamoo.t vmammh.0 mmvwv¢.0 mmmmvm.0 mommmm.0 NOHONM.0 vmomm.bm ambaamo. Nmmmaoo. hmmvmoo. Hmm.mmh bwqooo. >0PH.0HN Nmmmmma. mammvao. Hb0v0H0.t ¢H0m.wvm mbHNv00.t hH> cmwz Suzummom Quaamuou unconmom Hmuoumom Qumucomu mcool umcmnmom Qumamuou Qumucnmu nusuoaom Hmuoumom lllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +llllll|ll Ham>uoucH .ucoo wmmfi .uum .vum wNNm.m0HmN va llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +lllllllll mmH0.mvaH mvm m0m.mbmfibm m llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +lllllllll Nm.HMH u hbmm.0 hmmm.0 0000.0 0H.mm mmN mm: uoom noumsvmrm mom ooumswmrm m A noum Amam .m who no Honssz 0m m2 MU vm.mmwmmflb Hm.0mmvmmv mm.bbmmmmm mm Hmsoflmom Hove: wousom anUAU .IIH¢_chA val coauddsnom no Oulnvm uSO£UdB_.coququOm oauuocmldo .v.n.ov 174 m®m00.m0 mmmmmvo. 0¢mvm.at vaHOHo. vvmawoo. mmvmm.mm 00I0NF.N mmwoboo. mva0.NN 00NMNH0.I 00NNH0.MI Hmwmhoo. I Hvflmmoo.t N¢N.H00I I 00I0Nm.vl mwflmvoo. Ham>umucH .ucoo wmmg mmHm¢.Hmm> «ma llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +ll|llll|l mmomm.mmma has mob.mo>~mm n lllllllll Illllllllllllllllllll+lllllllll h0H.Hv H0bb.0 thb.0 0000.0 m0.00m mmv mm: uoom u omumsvmlm mod n noumsvmrm m A noum u .bmv .b 0m n one no Hmnfidz _u_Am mma.ml 0vm.ma 0mm.ml mbm.HI wmm.bl wmm.0H u mmmamm.0 «FOHHM.0 NDNNHN.0 Nm000N.0 hvmvho.0 wbmmv0.0 Nm¢Nm0.0 mmvflh.mfl mbmmvfio. mmmmmmv. vmhmooo. m000000. «Nm0.mma 00IMmm.v thmooo. .uum .cum MU bmbam.mm mmmmao. «vmth.NI 0000000. mvmhhoo.t mmm0.hmml 00I0N0.MI vammoo. .uooo 0v.HNmomHm Nm.mmmHNh wm.bmmmmvm mm _ hH> Gmmz _ £u3ummom _ Hausa _ Qumamuou _ Qumuccmu _ Unmom _ uncovmoa _ Hmuoumom _ mcoul _ umcmnmom _ amped _ Qumamuou _ Qumucvmu _ £u3ummom _ Unmom _ Hmuouaom ''''''''' IIII-In"I"I-l'nl'lu'l'I'InT'l-I-II'"- _ ncomxo _ Hmsnfimmm _ Hobo: _ wousom ands-csoa .uoanuaun> Han nuaz_.eo«uuoumom cauuoeuaao .H.u.o. 175 Nmflmmm.0 mNNHHm.0 mwhmam.0 N00¢0N.0 mvmbv0.0 Hmmvv0.0 hH> cmmz cuzummom mecca Qumamuou mumucomu Hmuoumom umcmoaoa mmmm.0HH maobmmo. N00¢HN.HI mvmmmoo. mN00m00.I mvam.0HHI 0vmmv00. m0m00.mm 00Hm0N0.I wmmmm.ml vmovboo. Hmvv000.I waH.MN0I ¢00¢N00. wvm.vl www.ma .HHm.bI HwaH.mH thbmao. mohamm¢. Mbflwooo. mvm0000. mmm~.mha mr0m000. mombh.mm «Hmmvoo. Hmwm0H.Nl hHNwmoo. 0N0b000.t 00¢0.0hvl wbmmmoo. mcool uncoomom Hausa mumamuou ammucnmu nusuomom Hmuoumom 0mamv.amm> vmv llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +lllllllll momav.amma 0Nv 0H0.mhmmmm m llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +lllllllll mvm.mv u Mbmr.0 movh.0 0000.0 mm.m0m mM¢ mm: uoom noumsvmrm wed nmumsvmrm m A noun Ammv .0 mno no Honesz vb m2 MU 0v.HNm00Hm hm.hvmmmm HH.vh0m0mm mm Hmsowmom Hove: oousom nmflnu::oa .COAUIdamom uo lunnvm uaonudz_.coaunouuom Daunocmaan AN.«.OV 176 0thmm.0 00mvHN.0 mmbmom.0 thNma.0 mmmv00.0 mvma00.0 mH> cmmz nusuomom mumflmuou Qumucnmu umcmomom Unmom Hmuouaom v00000v. 000v000. 000v0H0. mv00000.t 00NN.0HH 00I0¢0.NI Nmmbvoo. moro0.~mt v00H00. vhmamoo. 0500000.! 0000.0hml 00Im00.vl mm00m00. bmm.0 000.0H 0v0.0HI vmm.HI 000.5! N00000.0 v00h000. mm00000. mvmmooo. mmv.¢ba 00Im0h.v mhmvooo. 00000.0HI vbmambo. wmmmoo. NO0N000.t mm00.mmml 00t0h0.Ml Hammoo. mcool uncoumom Qumamuou Qumucumu £u3ummoa Unmoa Hmuoumom Hm.Nv u 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 Hh.mNN mmv mm: uoom noumsvmrm hum umumsvmtm m A noum Ammv .0 0m mno mo Monfisz bmmma.omba 0Nv mv0.h00v0v 0 llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +lllllll|| m2 up. vNN.th00h 0N.Nvmvmwm mm Hmsuwmmm Hobo: mousom unfinuctoa .fllnt baud uaonuwz..cownn0um0m adv-ocmufln Am.N.Uv 177 mm.o _ mH> coo: llllllllllllllllllllll +||I|l|lll omommm.o mo.H _ nuzuoooo Hammam.o mo.¢ _ ouoamoou Hormo~.o me.v _ monocomu mm»a¢a.o Hm.o _ Honouooo mmmmmfi.o m~.h _ omcooooo llll llllllllllllllllll +1 llllllll mH>\H .mH> _ mannaum> moamo.¢m mommmo.m moo.o Hmm.~ oevmmm.> mompm.ma _ mcoon mmmommo. mmeapqo. ooo.o HNH.F oovamoo. Hoaamoo. _ umcooaoo mmqaoflo. oarmpoo. ooo.o pmfl.¢fi mmmoooo. abommoo. _ ouoaouoo Noaomoo.u mmmomoo.u ooo.o hov.mu mommooo. «mamboo.u _ monocomu smmfib.mpu mvhm.vm>- mfio.o mom.~- ~m~m.mma msqo.¢mvu . nozuoooo Hmomoo. mommooo. ooo.o mmm.v enamooo. mmmvfloo. _ Hmoooooo llllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +lllllllll Ham>uouoH .ucoo mmmH _u_Am o .uum .oum .uooo _ ocoaxo mm... u mm: boom mmamo.fimme an. mv.H~momHm _ Hobos >v~>.o u oouosomum nod uuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuu + uuuuuuuuu mpmb.o u ooumsomum mmNHH.v~o~ mm. ve¢.¢vmmom _ Hmsoflmom oooo.o u m A ooum Hoa.mmvvmv m Ho.>eammm~ _ Hoooz mv.m- u Ammo .m an uuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuuu s ...... +unu ...... mmv u ago no noossz m2 no mm _ oousom ands-c308 .uOnt fiend val coauddamom Ho Chunvu uaonudk..cowuuoumtm Oduuocmada Av.N.U. APPENDIX D: FIXED EFFECTS REGRESSIONS rm Amofluoomumu bay H00v.m0b mmom0mN. vm0v0a0. 0000.0vml 0N0.0POH 0000000.! .Hm>umucH 00NH.0N0 0NHOv00. HOMHO. M000.0H0I HN¢0V.H>I m0bva0.r .ucoo mmmg 0NHm.0m0 N000HNH. 0H000H0. 0HN0.vm>I qomh.mm0 m0N0H0.I maoul umcoomom muaamuou Quaucomu nuzummom Hmuoumom |":ll'-l'-|"'l'|ll|'l'll'lll'l'|'|""II"|'|-"|'|I'I|"I"|'|II"II'|I'I| 0000.0 00.00 000N.0 00NN.0 MH00.0 ma 5H mmm m A poem Ammm .m Vb Hamuo>o coo3uon capo“: omum mpo no nonadz «wanna ”do Nmm.mm u Ammm.oflvm mmm.m voHNH.mo pmo.~ Hemommo. moo.HH Hmmvfloo. omm.p- mmoom.mm mmm.a momm.o~m map..- mmmflmoo. o .uum .oom mmom.o- u mmvm.om~ u nmpom.mm. u osmm.vbm u .cowuuouoou Anx .xlsvuuoo Axl: + uHxHoVUm 3 xsaom s. so. .caouaz. uuoouuouooxwu .H.H.o. 179 Ammfluoooumo 0V V000.va 000v00.H 0000H0. N000H.¢0 00v0.000 000VH00. 000000N.I 5000000.: 00HH000. H00.H0vl 0vmb.m0ml 000N0N0.I m00h.0NN H0000H0. 0NON000. v000.00HI v0N0.N0HI MHH0MH0.I uncooaoa Qumamuou mumucomu nuzumaom Hmuoumoa llllllllllllllll +ll|lll|ll 0000.0 v0.00 H0hH.0 000H.0 vm>>.0 0H 0 00 a A ooum .mb .m Hamuo>o cmmxuon 00 canon: om-m mno mo Honfisz ooaoao noun; mmm.oH u Ame.mvm mmm.a momo.HHH H00.H Nvmfiwhm. h00.> 0m>oaoo. mvv.Hu v0>o.>HH m0m.ou Hmov.~0m Hom.Hu mmmbboo. u .uum .oum mvm>.ou u b0¢0.0¢fl n 0H>N0.>~ u n00m.mvfi u .cowuuouoou Anx .xlsvuuou Axis + uHxloVUm Au xHovom 3. son .oanuaz. ouoouuouooxdm .u.H.o. 180 Amofluoomumo HHV ooo.o >000.Nb0 HO0HO0H. 0000000. 0000.000 0bN.vvv0 0HON000. N00.Nb 000.0H 00v.0r u A0vH.0HVh 00000.00 0000000. 0vHON00. N000.0HH 00Nv.0mh 000vv00. 00v0.000 N000000. 0N0va0. 000.HN0I 00090000 v0000H0.I mcool uncooaoa Quaamuou Qumucvmu nuznoaom Hmuoumom 0000.0 v0.00 0H00.0 00HH.0 Navb.0 0H HH 00H 00>.v00 ooo.o 0HN00HH.I 005.0 N0000H0. 000.0 0000.0v0l 000.0 000.H00 >00.0 N0000N0.I 000.0 .ucou 000a _u_Am h A Doum A0vH .0 00 Hamum>o cmozuon aflooflz oo-m a a mno 00 qu552 uoauao Hausa 00>>.0I hHHO.NON 0000.00 HHNh.v0N Anx .xlsvuuoo Axls + uHxlmVUm A» xmovom c. 5:8 .cowooouoou “casuwzv nuoouuarucxah .0.H.n. I81 Amofiooooooo HHL 000.0 mpv.pm u Amvfi.ofivm _ x mmoo.avm ~mmo.ofim . ooo.o oo~.m hammm.mm mmmfi.mho _ mooon mmommbm. hmHOHoo. mvo.o omm.H moovOAO. omvflovfi. _ “moooooo mmomfimo. phvmmflo. ooo.o Ham.m Hmmfioo. «moohfio. _ mooaoooo momv.fimm- ommo.m>mu ooo.o mme.mu mmmm.HHH o~mm.mmpu . oooooomu moo.pmbm mmv~0.0fl . evo.o ooo.m Hmmm.mop mmm.oovH _.Eo3uoooo Hfimo>oo.u omvmbflo.u ooo.o ems..- pmommoo. mooflmao.u _ Honouooo lllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll lllllllllllllllllllIl+llll|llll ”HosooooH .oooo wmmfi _o_Am o .oom .oom .oooo _ ooooxo oooo.o u m A ooom mo.m> u Amva .m we Hmom.o u Haoooso vom~.o u ooozooo I mmH>.o u cane“: worm mamm.ou n Lox .x :voooo ma u a mom~.mmm. n Axis + omxmovom HH u o Howam.oo u Au xlovom moH u moo 0o Hooasz mmv.m>m u Ax ovum “50.20.“: undefinom on 003.5 .codnuouoou .cwnuwzv uuo¢uu¢tflwxwh Av . H . a. 182 Amofluoooumo 00 005.00 llllllllllllllllllllllllllll llllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll+lllllllll u A05.0vm _ x mNHO.mmm 0m50.moq. _ moool vflomom. menmflmo.- _ omoooooo vanmoo. mpomvflo. _ anoaoooo mmmm.mm~ 0~.m~mu _ ouoooomu mmvo0m >m~mmv.m _.sozooooo mmmmmoo. Hmmmooo. _ Hooooooo Hum .Uum .umoo _ Unmmxm 0000.550 0000.00: 000000. 00H0000.| 0005000. 5005000. 0000.H00 0000.000: 0H0.05NH 000.H50H| 000000. 55000H0.| .Hm>umu:H .ucou 000_ 0000.0 u h A noum 00.0H u A05 .0 00 0000.0 u Hamum>o 0000.0 n cmmzuon 5500.0 n canvas Umlm 0H u a 0 u a 00 u one 00 nonadz ounum 05H5.0I 0H05.05H 05000.00 000H.05H Anx .xlsvuuou Axls + uHxHova Au xlmvvm Ax ovum 0:9 no 000% 0:9 cu uawuwo .GOMQuOHOGH Acflsuwsv.uuoouuarvoxwh .0.H.00 183 Amofluoooumo 00v 55000.00 0500000. 000H000. 00000.00 0000.50” 0000000. 0000.0 05.000 0000.0 0000.0 0005.0 00 00 000 00000.00I 0505000.I 0000000. 0H00.HHHI 0000.00HI 0H00000.I .ucou 0000 h A poem AH00 .0 a a one 00 nonasz aamuobo coozuon cflnufiz worm nawsuczoa ~04 .GOMQuOuoou .cwn»03. mucouMOIvoxwh 00 000.00 H AH00.0000 000.HI 50005.00 000.H 0000050. 000.5H 05H0000. 000.0I 05000.00 000.0 .0000.50H 050.0 5000N00. u .Hum .Uum 0000.0: H 00H05.00 u 00000.00 u 0000.00 u 00000.00: 0000000. 000000. 00050.00I 550H0.00 0000000. maool uncovmom Quaamuou Quaucvmu £03uomoa .Hmuouaom Anx .xlsvuuoo Axls + uHxHova Au xuovom c. 38 «0.0.0. 184 Amo0uomoumo 00 0000.550 000500.0 5000000. 0050.000 0000.005 0000000. 0000.000: 5005000. 0000000. 0500.000: 0000.005: 0050000.: mcoul umawumom Qum0muou Quaucvmn £03uoaom 0muouaoa 0000.0 00.00 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 00 0 00 m A song A50 .0 00muo>o coozuwn oflsuflz omum H a one no nonadz unwsnc3oa Gouda .c00unouoou .cwnuwzv «900MHOIGOK0M 00. Anx .xlsvuuoo Axl: + uHxlvam 000.0 .0 u A50.000 _ 000.0 .0 0000.050 00000.00 _ 000.0 .0 0500000. 0000000. _ 000.0 .0 0000000. 0000000. _ 050.0 .0: 0000.000 05000.55: _ 000.0 .0: 0000.000 00000.00: _ 000.0 .0: 0000000. 0005500.: _ _u_Am .Hum .vum .0000 _ 0000.0: u 0505.000 H 00000.00 u 0000.000 u A» xmovom Ax :vom 00.0.0. 185 mcool umcmoaoa Qum0muou Qumuavmu nuzuumoa 0muoumoa Anx .xlsvuuoo Axis + ulxlmvvm Ao:x:o0om Aoofiuoooooo 0N0 ooo.o npfi.ov u Ammm.mmvm _ mmmo~.om 0Hmm~.0m- 0mm.o 5mm.o- «Hmom.om ammom.om- _ Hmmmmmm. vmmflmno.- ~>~.o 000.0 mmmmmmo. mpmefimo. _ mmvfimoo. Hofihqoo. 000.0 omm.00 mvmmooo. momvmoo. _ mamma.vm noflo.m~0- «00.0 mmb.o- Hmmm.m0 mommfl.mm- _ www.mom Hmmfl.m>0- pm0.o mmm.o 0mom.pm0 mammm.mm _ Nflmppoo. mmmmmoo.u omm.o mmo.0 vflhmmoo. mvmhmoo. _ llllll llllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll+lllllllll .0msooooH .uooo wmm_ _o_Am u .oom .oom .uooo _ oooo.o u m A ooum mm.mma u Ammm .m mwmm.o u Hamoo>o momm.o u ooozooo mmmmoo H CHSUH3 Umlm 0mmN.Ol H m0 n a www.mv H mm u o boo.- u 0mm u moo 0o nooeoz mmmfim.00 u ua0£nczoa 00uEm .c00nuouoau .cwnu03. mucouuo:voxwh Ax::0oo 00.0.00 um Amm0uoooumo 00v 50000.00: 0500000. 0000000. 0000.000 0000.000 0000000. 0000.500: 0000000.: 0000000. 05000.50 0050.000: 0000000. 0000.050: 5000000.: 0000000. 0000.000 0500.000: 5000000. mcool unconmom Qua0muou Quaucomu casuomom 0muoumom 0000.0 00.000 0000.0 0000.0 0005.0 u 00 u 00 000 :u005002 uuuonuaom :0 «90:0:309 .cowuuouoou a A ooom A000 .m 00muo>o somzuon cflnoflz om-m vb one 00 “00852 005.00 u A000.m000 nmm.m: mo0>m.mv 000.0- encamno. om~.m mmomooo. 00~.N 00000.00 o>0.0- mmom.000 005.0 0000000. u .uum .oum mmmm.o: u H0ov.m00 n 0000.00 u m000.000 u 00x .xlsvuuou Axls + ulemVUm 30:30... a. so... .owsufiz. ouoouuonooxam .0.~.o. 187 000.00 X mcool. umawvaom 0000muou ammucvmu 20300900 0muoumom 03x .xlsvuuou Axls + ulxflmvnm 00:0 0000 00000000000 000 000.0 u 0000.0000 _ 00000000 0000.00- 000.0 000.0 00000.00. 000000.0 _ 000000.0 0000000. 000.0 000.0 0000000. 000000.0 _ 0000000. 0000000. 000.0 000.00 0000000. 0000000. _ 00000.00 0000.000- . 000.0 000.0- 000.00 0000.000- _ 0000.000 00000.00- .000.0 000.0 0000.000 0000.000 _ 000000.: 0000000.- 000.0 000.0- 0000000. 0000000.- _ llll llllllllllll .llllllllllllllr lllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll + lllllllll 000>00000 .0000 0000 _0_A0 0 .000 .000 .0000 _ 0000.0 n 0 A 0000 00.00 n 0000 .0 00 0000.0 u 00000>o 0000.0 u 0003000 0000.0 n 000003 00:0 0000.0- u 00 u 0 0000.000 u 00 u 0 00000.00 u 000 u 000 00 000002 000.000 u 00.00 000 00 00.0 000 00 000000300 .0o0uuauoou 00:0000 0:03003. QUOGHHOIUGKAH 00.0.00 APPENDIX E: GENERAL LINEAR MODEL REGRESSIONS 188 0000.000 0000000. 0000.000 0000000. 0000.000: 050.0000 0505000.: 0005.000 000000. 05000.00 0000000. 0000.000: 000.0000: 0000000.: 05000.00 050000. 05000.00 0000000. 00000.05 5000.005 0000000. .005.000 0000000. 00000.00 0050000. 0000.000: 0000.000: 0000000.: cu000 Qua0muou unaucvmu 30300000 0muoumom 00.000 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 50.00 000 002 uoom Umumsvm:m 00¢ Umumsvmlm m A noum 0000 .0 090 no amnesz vb 0000.00000 000 IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII +Iu|I-'II.IIIIII. 0000.00000 000 00.000000 0 ||||||||||||||||||||||||| +|||nllulu|l.l 02 0U 00.0000005 00.0050000 00.0000000 00 00000000 0000: muusom uwcmv :0000 0000muou oumucnmu nuZumaom 0muoumom Unmaxm mmmuomu . uOMuwo 004_.coduuouu¢m 0anoznunccwn 0auocou .0.m. 189 0005.000 0000000. 0000500.: 0000000. 0000.000: 00000.00: 0050000. 500.00 0005.0 5005.0 0000.0 00.000 000 00000.50 0000500. 05500.00: 0000000. 0000.000: 5050.005: 000000. 002 uoom Umumsvm:m 00¢ Umum:0m:0 m A noum A000 .0 mac mo umnadz 00 005.00 000.0: 00000.00 0000000. 000000.0 0000000. 0000.50 0000.000 0000000. 00000.0005 000 ||||||||||||||||||||||||||||| +I"'|Iu'|l 00000.0000 000 00.000000 0 llllllllllllllllllllllllllllll +lllll|lll 02 MC 0000.000 0500000. 0500.00: 0000000. 0050.000: 0000.000: 0000000. 00.0000000 00.000000 00.0500000 00 au000 Qum0muou unaucvmu nuzuomon 0muouaoa Hasnfimmm Hmnoz muusom umcmu cu000 Qua0muou ouaucnmu nuzumaoa 0muouaoa vammxw mmmummu . nmwsuczoa 004..:000uouo¢m 0ovoznuaocaq 0auoc00 00.00 APPENDIX F: FIXED EFFECTS REGRESSION WITH LOCATION VARIABLE 190 Amm0uomm umo >00 0000.005 0000000. 0000000. 0000.000: 000.0500 0000000.: 0000.000 0000000. 00000. 0000.000: 00000.05: 0050000.: 0000.000 0000000. anmamouuv 5000000. 0000.005: 0005.000 000000q: >u0mcmv :00umUO0 Qua0muou unaucvmu nuznmaoa 0muouaoa 0000.0 00.00 0000.0 0000.0 0000.0 00 u 50 000 m A noum .mmm .m 00 00mum>o :mwzumn sang“: vmum H a 030 00 umnadz mmm.mm n Ammm.0000 mmm.m «mama.m0 pmo.~ 0000mmo. 000.00 Hmmvfioo. 000.0: mmmmm.mm mmm.H mmmm.omm mmb.0: mmmfimoo. u .uum .num mmmm.o- u mmvm.om~ u pmbmm.mm_ u mpmm.vp~ u Anx .xlsvuuoo Axl: + uHxlvam Au xmmvnm Ax :vcm «mango .oannfiun> cofiuaooq gags..cofiuuouuou .cfigufis. uuoauuouvoxwm .0. APPENDIX G: SAMPLE REGRESSION DATA 191 000.0 80.00 00.0 3.0 000.00 000 000— 000. 0 2.0.0.. 00.0 3.0 000.00 000 000.. 30.0 $560 010 090 2360 00 £80 80. 0 000.00 00. c 3.0 000.00 000 000.. .K0.0 9360 00.0 090 9000 QM 02: E0. 0 000.5 00. o 3.0 30.00 000 000.. 30.0 $860 00.0 FQO 3300 $3 93— 30.0 3800 93 0Q0 9800 33 $60 20.0 £800 96 090 2300 38 #00 000.0 000.00 00. o 3.0 30.00 000 000.. 000. 0 000.3. 00. c 3.0 000.3 08 000.. 000. 0 08.0.. 00.0 3.0 000.3 000 0000 000.0 000.0— 000 3. 0 000.00 000 0000 000.0 000.0— 000 3. c {0.00 000 000— 08.0 000. 00 00.0 00. o 03.8 000 30.. $2.20!... $80 0320 090 090 #060 20 £80 2&0 20.mw .86 090 3:00 03 . :80 08.0 000. 00 00.0 00.0 03.00 000 000.. 30. 0 000. 00 3.0 00.0 03.2 000 000— 80. 0 000. 00 3. o 00.0 000.00 03 30.. 000.0 000 .00 3. o 00.0 000.00 000 0000 80.0 000. 8 00. o 00.0 03.00 000 0000 000.0 000 .00 00.0 00.0 000.00 03 000— 03 .0 03. 00 3.0 00.0 03.00 000 000. .80.0 38.00 0&0 090 mfld0 28 980 000.0 03. 00 00.0 00.0 000.00 000 000.. RE; 0920 .K.0 090 9800 08 380 03.0 000 .00 K. o 00.0 05.00 30 000.. 08.0 30.3 ms. 0 00.0 000.3 08 000.. 03... 03.0.. 0:. 00.0 03.00 08 30.. 0.3.... 20.52.52“. .EQIDEE 53201: 532668. .izsod2. A3085 .2896 88’ 28 000900 .32. cowuuouoom 009.30 00.0. 192 83 ...... .... .... ...... 8. 82 8... .... .. .... .... .....8 .8 82 ..3 8.... .... .... ....8 .8 82 8... ....8 .... .... .88 .8 .8. 83 8.8 .... .... ....8 .8 .8. ..3 .2... ... .... ......8 8. .8. 83 8..... .... .... 8.... .8 82 8... .8... 8.. .... 8.... .8 82 ..3 8.... .... .... ...... 8. ..2 .8 ...... 8.. .... 8.... .8 82 ... 8.... 8.. .... 8.... .... 82 .8 8..... .... .... ...... 8. 82 .8 ...... 8.. .... ...... ... 82 2. ...... .... .... .2... 8. .8. .8 .... 2 .... .... 2...... ... ..2 25...... ...... ....8 8.. .... 8.... .8 82 ...... 8.... 8.. .... .8... 8. 82 .... . .8... 8.. .... .8... ... 82 .8. . .88 8.. .... 8..... 8. .8. 8... 2.8 8.. .... ...... .8 .8. .... 8‘8 .... .... 2.... ... 82 ...... .2 ... ... .... .8... ... 82 8... .8... .... .... ...... ... 82 .8. 8.... 8.. .... ...... 8. .8. 8... .8... 8.. .... 3...... ... 82 ...... 8.8 .... .... 8..... .8 82 8... ....8 ... .... .8... ... 82 ...... ....8 .... 8.. 8.... 8. 82 ...... .88 ... .... 8...... .2 .8. .3... 8.8 .... .... ...... .2 .8. amazes. ..s 2...8... .22.. .8 2.2.. .8. .3. .5 ...... ...... .... item a... £23... nmwnugoa Juno newuuouoom 009.30 .060