IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII I I '3. ‘m‘cszs Illllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllzlllllll 31293 01771 LIBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled THE LONG-RUN DEMAND FOR MONEY FUNCTIONS IN TAIWAN (1961:4-1997z3): COINTEGRATION AND STABILITY presented by Ching-yi Chiang has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph . D , Economics degree in Date /-7~/8//qg MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0- 12771 PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINE return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE I DATE DUE DATE DUE SEP 0 5 2005' 1M animus-m4 THE LONG-RUN DEMAND FOR MONEY FUNCTIONS IN TAIWAN (1961:4-1997z3): COINTEGRATION AND STABILITY BY Ching-yi Chiang A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1999 ABSTRACT THE LONG-RUN DEMAND FOR MONEY FUNCTIONS IN TAIWAN (196l:4-1997:3): COINTEGRATION AND STABILITY BY Ching-yi Chiang This dissertation compares the performance of the long- run demand functions for alternative new definitions of money (MIA, MlB, MlBP, and M2) in Taiwan for the same sample period (1961:4-1997z3). Various unit—root tests cannot reject that the variables chosen for each function (real balances, real GNP, and short-term interest rates) are characterized as IICl) processes. Using residual-based cointegration tests (Phillips and Ouliaris 1990, Gregory and Hansen 1996), rue found cointegration evidence 1J1 all four demand functions for real balances. However, the parameter stability ‘tests cflf Hansen (1992b) suggest that the :most stable long-run relationship occurs in the demand for real MlB equation. MlB being stable is consistent with the transactions-demand theory which links real money balances demanded with a measure of the volume of real transactions (real GNP) and opportunity costs of holding money balances. Instability detected in the demand for broadly defined money (M18? and M2) is explained by misspecification. Low liquidity in the non-M18 components suggests that the demand for broader measures may be justified by portfolio or speculative-demand. theory; hence, wealth instead of .real GNP, or a measure of volatility of alternative assets' returns enters the equation. Johansen's (1991) trace and max-K test establish that there is only one cointegrating vector in the system. For the demand for real MlB function, the equilibrium income elasticity! is around 1.50, and interest elasticity is - 0.41, which are robust to four alternative estimators. While the price homogeneity is not rejected, the unitary income elasticity is rejected by the data. The rejection of weak exogeneity status of the variables invalidates the inference conducted in single equation error correction model in estimating the long-run. demand. for real MlB function in Taiwan. To my Mother, Kwey-jen Deng Chiang and my Father, Ching-jen Chiang ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I wish to express my deepest gratitude to Professor Robert H. Rasche for years of assistance and guidance throughout this research. As my research adviser, he has been very generous to give me valuable comments and suggestions and also been very patient to guide to be a researcher' so that I cxui grow' professionally. His broad knowledge of Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics expand my ways of thinking about these fields. Through his lectures, I obtained the first hand knowledge of these fields and constant intellectual stimulation as well. This enables me to fit disarranged pieces of knowledge together in an efficient way and then to form a clearer picture of the multi-dimensional jigsaw puzzle—Monetary Economics. His interpretations (ME economic theories vnifli thoughts spiced with interesting examples, sometimes jokes, inspired me to study Economics not only with discipline but also with pleasure. Moreover, Ii greatly' appreciate Professor's assistance in constructing the interest rate variables in my study, which shortened the length of time for me to complete this dissertation. Without his assistance, I must have been still struggling with the data problem, which would take years to resolve without such expertise and experience. I am very grateful for all of what I have learned from Professor Rasche during these years at MSU. I also wish to thank. the other two members of' my guidance committee, Professor Jeffrey' Wooldridge and Professor Christine E. Amsler. Their valuable comments and suggestions encouraged we tx> think further how tx> improve this study. I greatly appreciate that they generously gave me their time and support. I would also like to thank Professor Peter Schmidt for kindly providing me references. I also appreciate Professor Chingnun Lee for his help with the data and for his generosity of allowing me to get access to Taiwanese economic data through internet. I want to mention some friends I made at MSU. Ling— Huang Yu is a friend whose warm heart, perseverance, and critical mind are what I admire her most about; we went through good times and bad times together during my graduate career. II also greatly appreciate Jing-I Ina, Mei-Yu Teai, and Meihsin Chou for their support and encouragement. These unique individuals enrich my life at MSU in several ways. I wish them the very best. Last but most I would like to thank my mother, Kwey-jen Den Chiang, and my father Ching-jen Chiang, for their unconditional love, continuos encouragement, and financial support. Words are unable to express my gratitude to them. All the accomplishments I have made belong to them. Their vi devotion to children is beyond what I can understand. Besides, I also thank my aunt Fang—kwey, who constantly calls me to eat properly. Her words turned out to be more nutritious than food. I would also like to thank my sister Chiu-juan for being very considerate of me, providing me suggestions, sharing her experience in life with me, and frequently forwarding jokes to me. vii TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ........................................... xi LIST OF FIGURE ......................................... xiv CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION .............................................. 1 CHAPTER 2 THE DEMAND FOR MONEY: THEORY .............................. 6 I: THEORY REVIEW ........................................ 6 l The Motives of the Demand for Money ................ 6 2 A Missing Chapter in the Theoretical Money Demand Literature: The Time (Energy, Resources) Saving Aspect of the Use of Money ......................... 7 II: TRANSACTIONS DEMAND FOR MONEY MODEL: A SHOPPING TIME MODEL ......................................... 10 1 Assumptions ....................................... 10 (1) Preferences ................................... 10 (2) Time constraint ............................... ll (3) The multiperiod budget constraint ............. 15 2 The Constrained Multiperiod Utility Maximization Problem ........................................... 20 3 Properties of the Money Demand Function ........... 24 4 Stability of the Money Demand Function ............ 28 5 Cash—in-Advance Model versus the Shopping Time Model ............................................. 32 6 Empirical Issues: Arguments in the Money Demand Function .......................................... 34 III: THE STABILITY OF THE AGGREGATE MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION AND ITS POLICY IMPLICATION ............... 37 1 Quantity Theory of Money and Monetarism ........... 39 IV: THE ARGUMENTS IN THE TAIWANESE DEMAND FOR MONEY FUNCTIONS: DATA DESCRIPTION ....................... 43 1 Measure of Money .................................. 45 2 Scale Variable .................................... 48 vm 3 Measure of the Opportunity Cost of Holding Money..49 (1) The own rate on money ......................... 51 (2) Unorganized money market rate ................. 52 CHAPTER 3 STATISTICAL PROPERTIES OF UNIVARIATE TIME SERIES IN THE DEMAND FUNCTIONS FOR REAL BALANCES IN TAIWAN: 1961:4-1997:3 ............................................ 60 I: INTRODUCTION ........................................ 60 II: UNIVARIATE UNIT-ROOT TESTS ......................... 63 1 The HEGY Seasonal Unit—Root Tests ................. 67 2 The Dickey-Fuller Unit-Root Tests ................. 78 3 The KPSS Stationarity Tests ....................... 84 CHAPTER 4 THE LONG-RUN DEMAND FOR MONEY FUNCTIONS IN TAIWAN (1961:4-1997:3): COINTEGRATION AND STABILITY ............. 91 I: EQUILIBRIUM RELATIONSHIP AND COINTEGRATION .......... 91 II: RESIDUAL BASED COINTEGRATION TESTS ................. 93 1 Introduction ...................................... 93 2 Phillips and Ouliaris (1990) Z; and 22 tests ...... 95 3 OLS Estimates: Asymptotic Results ................. 99 4 Inference of Cointegrating Vectors .............. 100 5 Empirical Study: The Existence of the Long-Run Money Demand Functions in Taiwan (1961:4-1997:3) ................................................ 101 (1) The demand for real MIA equation ............ 104 (2) The demand for real MlB equation ............ 105 (3) The demand for real MlBP equation ........... 105 (4) The demand for real M2 equation ............. 105 (5) Summary ..................................... 111 III: THE STABILITY OF THE LONG-RUN DEMAND FOR MONEY FUNCTIONS IN TAIWAN (1961:4—1997z3) ............. 112 1 Residual Based Tests for Cointegration in Models with Regime Shifts: Gregory and Hansen (1996) Z; and Z: Tests .................................... 113 2 Hansen (1992b) LM Tests for Parameter Instability in Cointegrating System ......................... 118 3 Empirical Study: The Stability of the Long-Run Money Demand Functions in Taiwan (1961:4-1997z3) 121 (1) The demand for real MlA equation ............ 123 (2) The demand for real MlB equation ............ 126 (3) The demand for real MlBP equation ........... 128 k (4) The demand for real M2 equation ............. 131 (5) Summary ..................................... 132 IV: JOHANSEN’S FULL INFORMATION MAXIMUM LIKELIHOOD ESTIMATION ....................................... 151 1 Introduction .................................... 151 2 Empirical Study: The Number of the Cointegrating Vectors in Taiwanese Money Demand Data (1961:4-1997z3) ................................. 153 (1) The Taiwanese demand for real MIA data ...... 155 (2) The Taiwanese demand for real MlB data ..... 161 V: ESTIMATION AND TESTS OF LINEAR RESTRICTIONS ON THE LONG-RUN PARAMETERS OF DEMAND FOR REAL MlB IN TAIWAN .................................................. 167 1 Estimation of the Long-Run Income and Interest Elasticities .................................... 167 2 Tests of Linear Restrictions on Cointegrating Vectors (B) and the Adjustment Coefficients (a). 180 (1) Tests of linear restrictions on B ........... 180 (2) Weak exogeneity tests ....................... 182 3 Estimation of the Long-Run Impact Matrix II ...... 184 4 Summary ......................................... 185 CHAPTER 5 CONCLUSIONS ............................................ 189 APPENDIX 1 THE REDEFINED MONETARY AGGREGATES IN TAIWAN ............ 193 APPENDIX 2 SOURCES OF FUNDS BORROWED BY PRIVATE ENTERPRISES IN TAIWAN ................................................. 197 APPENDIX 3 TESTING FOR PRICE HOMOGENEITY OF THE MONEY DEMAND FUNCTIONS IN TAIWAN (1961:4-1997z3) .................... 199 APPENDIX 4 TESTING FOR NO COINTEGRATION BETWEEN THE UNORGANIZED MONEY MARKET RATE AND THE OWN RATE OF MONEY IN TAIWAN (196l:4-1997:3) ........................................ 202 BIBLIOGRAPHY ........................................... 206 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 2: 10: 11: 12: LIST IF TABLES HEGY tests for seasonal unit roots in quarterly aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances: 1961:4-1997:3 .................................. 74 DF tests for unit roots at zero frequency in quarterly aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances: 1961:4-1997:3 ................................... 80 KPSS stationarity tests for quarterly aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances (1961:4-1997:3): Model I: Regression with an intercept .................................... 87 KPSS stationarity tests for quarterly aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances (1961:4-1997:3): Model II: Regression with an intercept and a trend ........................ 88 DF-t tests for unit roots in the first difference of the aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances: 1961:4-1997:3 ...... 89 Testing for no cointegration in Taiwanese demand real MIA data .......................... 107 Testing for no cointegration in Taiwanese demand for real MlB data ...................... 108 Testing for no cointegration in Taiwanese demand for real MlBP data ..................... 109 Testing for no cointegration in Taiwanese demand for real M2 data ....................... 110 Critical values for residual-based cointegration tests .......................... 111 Cointegration tests with regime shifts and parameter constancy tests: real MIA data ..... 134 Cointegration tests with regime shifts and parameter constancy tests: real MlB data ..... 136 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table 13: 14: 15: 16: 17: 18: 19: 20: 21: 22: 23: 24: 25: 26: 27: 28: 29: Cointegration tests with regime shifts and parameter constancy tests: real MlBP data.... 138 Cointegration tests with regime shifts and parameter constancy tests: real M2 data ...... 139 Critical values for Z; and Z: tests .......... 141 Critical values for Lt, MeanF, and SupF tests 141 Residual misspecification tests .............. 157 Tests of the cointegration rank .............. 158 The eigenvector associated with the largest eigenvalue (vi) and the corresponding weights (W1) .......................................... 160 Residual misspecification tests .............. 161 Trace and 2““ tests .......................... 163 Normalized cointegrating vectors (fl) and error correction coefficients (a) ................. 166 Critical values for trace and 2m“ tests ...... 167 Estimated cointegrating relations: RMlB, = u + Oyy, + 8,fi + e, ................. 172 Estimated cointegrating relations: RMlB, = p + ny, + Gnmumm, + 8, ............. 173 Weak exogeneity tests: VAR(4) model .......... 186 Weak exogeneity tests: VAR(3) model .......... 187 VAR(4): Estimated long-run coefficients matrix: 1'] = afl’ .................................... 188 VAR(3) Estimated long—run coefficients matrix: 11 = afl’ .................................... 188 X“ Table Table Table Table A1: A2: A3: A4: New measures of money ........................ Sources of funds borrowed by private enterprises in Taiwan ........................ Testing for price homogeneity ................ Testing for no cointegration between the unorganized money market rate (umm) and the own rate of money (i) .................... xiii 194 197 200 203 Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure Figure 10: II: 12: 13: I4: 15: 16: LIST OF FIGURES Taiwanese money demand Data .................... 58 Growth rates of Taiwanese money demand data (1961:4-1997:3) ................................ 59 Time plot of Z(t) statistics for the demand for real MIA ................................. 142 Time plot of Z(a) statistics for the demand for real MIA ................................. 143 Time plot of Z(t) statistics for the demand for real MIB ................................. 144 Time plot of Z(a) statistics for the demand for real MIB ................................. 145 Time plot of Z(t) statistics for the demand for real MIBP ................................ 146 Time plot of Z(a) statistics for the demand for real MIBP ................................ 147 Time plot of Z(t) statistics for the demand for real M2 .................................. 148 Time plot of Z(d) statistics for the demand for real M2 ................................. 149 SupF test for demand for real MIA ........... 150 SupF test for demand for real MIB ........... 150 SupF test for demand for real MIBP .......... 150 SupF test for demand for real M2 ............ 150 The Actual and estimated MIB/P (Four-variable system) ...................... 174 The Actual and estimated MIB/P (Three-variable system) ..................... 175 xw Figure 17: The Actual and estimated MIB/P: OLS estimation .............................. 176 Figure 18: The Actual and estimated MIB/P: DOLS estimation ............................. 177 Figure 19: The Actual and estimated MIB/P: FM estimation ............................... 178 Figure 20: The Actual and estimated MIB/P: JOH ......................................... 179 XV CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION The aggregate demand for nmney function, which links money balances demanded with a scale variable and a measure of the opportunity cost of holding money balances, is an essential ingredient in macroeconomic analysis and its importance is associated with efficacy of monetary policy. As Keynes (1936) postulated long before, while a stable money demand relation under different state of nature does not guarantee the potence of the monetary policy, its instability certainly undermines the usefulness of manipulation of quantity of money in an economy as a central stabilizing device. Many macroeconomic models are built on a notion that the»:money' demand relation remains stable to analyze the effect of monetary policy on economic activity, such as Monetarist (Friedman, 1956, 1974), New Classical model (Sargent and Wallace, 1975), New Keynesian model (Mankiw, 1991), and the empirical real business cycle model (King, Plosser, Stock, and Watson, 1991). Finding an empirical stable money demand relation provides these models an empirical content. Numerous attempts to estimate money demand relations in Taiwan have been undertaken. Studies on Taiwanese money demand function concentrate on the Goldfeld-type (Goldfeld, 1973, 1976) partial adjustment model. Empirical evidence on the issue of stability based on Taiwanese data is mixed, depending (N1 the functional form, 'variables used, sample period studied, and the choice of estimating and testing procedure, see Hwang and Wu (1994) and Lin (1997) for a review. Using Engle-Granger (1987) ADF cointegration tests, Chang (1989) finds that there is TM) evidence of cointegration among real balances, real GNP, one-month time deposit rate for two monetary aggregates (real MIA and real MIB) but cointegration occurs in real M2 equation (using the same scale variable, and interest rate variable). The evidence from. the error-correction. model shows that the short-run specification for the demand for real M2 remains stable over the sample period (1964:1-1987z4). Lee (1994)1 examines the equilibrium relationship between real MIB, real GNP, and one—month time deposit rate over the sample period (1961:3-1992:4) using Johansen (1991) and Hansen and Johansen (1993) testing procedures. He finds that the demand for real MIB function shifted downward in the fourth quarter of 1982, while leaving the income and interest elasticity unchanged. 1 Ph.D dissertation, C.N. Lee, 1994, Department of Economics , Michigan State University. Also see the published version of Lee’s Ph.D dissertation (in Chinese) (1996). Conventionally, studies on Taiwanese money demand use bank deposit rates as a measure of opportunity cost of holding money balances. However, the characteristics of the financial structure in Taiwan — flourishing unorganized money markets (U.M.M.) - have been overlooked in the Taiwanese money demand literature. In the study, we argue that the interest rate on U.M.M., which has been recorded since 1947 but omitted in most of the early studies, is a relevant variable entering tflua money demand relationships and this interest rate may also play an important role in the macroeconomic analysis in Taiwan. The objective of this study is to investigate the stability of the long-run demand for money functions for four alternative new definitions of money by incorporating the characteristics of the financial structure in Taiwan. We estimate the equations using quarterly data from 196I:4 through I997:3. The sample period covers several regime shifts (two oil crises 1973, 1979, shifts from a fixed exchange rate regime 1x3 a floating' exchange rate regime 1978, and financial deregulation since 1980). Since VH3 do not have theories suggesting the appropriate definition of money for monetary analysis and particular empirical measures as clearly superior to others which yield more stable money demand relationships, we estimate the money demand functions for four measures of money (MIA, MIB, MlBP, and M2) and then compare their performance over the same sample period using the same econometric techniques to reveal which measure may serve a better guide to monetary policy. This dissertation is organized as follows. In Section I of CHAPTER 2, we briefly review the theories of the demand for money in the literature. In Section II, we derive a transactions demand for money model from a multiperiod utility maximization framework without imposing a cash-in- advance constraint. This model has solutions similar to those in Lucas (1988) and possesses some properties which help understand some empirical findings. In Section III the importance of aa stable aggregate money demand function in macroeconomic analysis is discussed. In Section IV we clarify some questions regarding the appropriate interest rate variable in the Taiwanese money demand functions a priori and describe the data series used in the study. In CHAPTER 3 the statistical properties of the data series are investigated in order to choose appropriate econometric techniques to study the money demand relationships. In Section I there is a brief discussion of how the time series analysis of models with unit roots has had a major impact on our understanding of the response of economic system.tx> shocks. In Section II vwa apply various univariUe unit root tests (Hylleberg, Engle, Granger, and Yoo 1990, Fuller 1976, Dickey and Fuller 1979, I981, Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin 1992) incorporating seasonality in the data to establish the order of integration of the individual time series. In CHAPTER 4 the empirical evidence of the long-run money demand relationships for four measures of money (MIA, MIB, MIBP, and M2) is explored and their stability during I961:4-1997:3 is examined. In Section I equilibrium concepts in terms of cointegration are sketched. In Section II the econometric methods for analyzing relationship among I(1) variables are introduced enui the empirical cointegration evidence in the four money demand functions is examined. Parameter stability in these four functions is investigated in Section III. In Section IV the order of cointegration rank in the demand for real MIB data is first examined and linear restrictions on the long-run parameters are estimated and tested using Johansen (I99I)'s general deterministic trend model. The robustness of the equilibrium income elasticity and interest elasticity is checked using four alternative estimators, (OLS, Stock and Watson 1993, Phillips and Hansen 1990, Johansen 1991). In CHAPTER 5 the conclusions are presented. CHAPTER 2 THE DEMAND FOR.MONEY: THEORY I: THEORY REVIEW 1 The MOtives of the Demand for MOney Keynes (1936) articulates three motives for liquidity- preference, namely, the transactions-motive, the precautionary-motive, and the speculative-motive. These three sources of liquidity-preference generate the demand for money. Baumol (I952), Tobin (1956), Miller and Orr (1966)1, by emphasizing the choice-making behavior of individuals and giving the transactions demand for money a microfoundaton, go further to investigate the optimal transactions cash holdings for the economic agent. They find that even the transactions demand for cash can be interest- elastic due to the existence of transactions costs between cash and interest-bearing assets. This contrasts with the 1 These models emphasize that the necessity of holding cash is to bridge the gap between receipts and expenditures. Under the assumptions that transactions are perfectly foreseen and occur in a steady stream, Baumol’s and Tobin's models apply reasonably well to salary-earning households. In constrast to the deterministic Baumol/Tobin model, Miller and Orr make the opposite assumption that the net cash flows are completely stochastic, building a money demand model for business firms. demand for transactions money developed from the quantity theory of money Fisher (1911) and the Cambridge approach (Marshall, Pigou), or Keynes (1936) who postulated that the effect of interest rates on the transactions money is negligible. Tobin (1958) explains that the speculative money demand comes from the risk averse behavior of the agent. The agent is uncertain of the future rate of interest on variable market yield monetary asset so he holds money in his investment balances to diversify the risk from the portfolio to avoid a loss from holding the non-money asset. Other than for the transactions purpose, economic agents hold idle balances in money even when money is dominated by many other monetary assets as a store of valuez. 2 A Missing Chapter in the Theoretical Mbney Demand Literature: The Time (Energy, Resources) Saving Aspect of the USe of Money The distinguishing feature between a barter economy and a money economy is the use of a medium of exchange (generally acceptable media of payment, money) in conducting transactions. In a barter economy, economic agents exchange goods and services for goods and services, whereas in a money economy, economic agents sell goods and services for 2 It is possible that a risk averter would choose to hold all his investment balances in non-money asset and not to hold.:money' at all. If the agent is risk lover,, he certainly plunges his entire investment balances into variable yield monetary assets (see Tobin I958). money and use money to purchase goods and services3. However money is defined empirically“, or whatever form it is held in, strictly speaking, by money we mean that money serves four functions: (1) as a medium of exchange, (2) as a standard of unit of account, (3) as a store of value (a temporary abode of purchasing power), and (4) as a final discharge of debts. The use of money as a medium of exchange and a store of value allows purchases and sales to be conducted independently cflf one another so ii: effectively eliminates the requirement of a “double coincidence of wants” in the exchange search process of a barter economy. As a unit of account and a final discharge of debts, it also reduces the number of rates of exchange (prices) between different items quoted in the market and simplifies the information in any transaction. The use.of money greatly reduces the time and resource devoted to exchange and therefore facilitates transactions. Without recognizing the time saving aspect of the use of money, it is hard to explain why money is used at all in the economy. The literature cited above recognizes that money 1i; indispensable III conducting transactions aumi the 3 Some transactions, of course, may be conducted through barter in a money-economy. transactions purpose is the reason why it is included in the portfolit> even. when. other assets with higher yields are available. The analyses presume that money is used in the transactions so the demand for money is always positive, which amounts to imposing a cash-in-advance (Clower) constraint in the model. However the fundamental reason for the use of money is unstated in these models, there is a missing chapter in the theoretical literature in explaining the money demand behavior. Saving (1971) fills this missing chapter in the money demand literature by emphasizing the medium-of—exchange role of money and time saving aspect of money. In his sophisticated model, it is demonstrated that without imposing a cash-in-advance restriction, we can still obtain a positive transactions demand for money. In the spirit of Saving (1971) and McCallum (Chapter 3, 1989) models, we build a transactions demand for money model from a utility maximization framework. The model tries to capture the notion in Friedman's (1956) restatement of the quantity theory of money that money is an asset held for the services which it provides and that these services and the low transactions cost associated with exchange of money for other assets (including physical goods) explain the 4 Empirical money is defined according to the relative ease (liquidity) with which an asset may be converted into “money”, a means of payment. existence a positive demand for money. Without a cash-in- advance restriction, the solutions of the model have similar properties to those in Lucas (1988), so our model provides a possible explanation for the cash-in-advance constraint in his model. The resulting money demand function also has some properties which may help understand some empirical findings in the money demand literature. II: TRANSACATIONS DEMAND FOR.MONEY MODEL: A SHOPPING TIME MODEL 1 Assumptions We assume complete certainty in order to abstract from precautionary and speculative demand for money and to concentrate on the transaction motive for holding money. (1) Preferences The agent is assumed to live for T periods. He gets utility out of real consumption of goods and services (c) and leisure time (L) enui he prefers to smooth out the consumption over the lifetime by borrowing and lending. Thus, at any point in time, e.g. period 1, preferences are described by the explicit multiperiod utility function as, 10 U = U(CI’CZ'HH'CT’.LI'LZ’"..'LT) T T = Zfl"'lnc, + aZa)"'lnL, 0 < (1,8,(9 < 1 (1,1) r=l (=1 where B and w are the intertemporal elasticities of consumption and leisure, respectively. a is the contemporaneous elasticity between consumption and leisure. U has properties of positive marginal utility, and diminishing marginal utility with respect to each c and L. (2) Time constraint The agent allocates each period of time (normalized as 1) into leisure (1;), work. (N}) and shopping (transaction time, 8,). The agent is assumed to be locked in a labor - contract, supplying' labor services inelastically (Ah) at real wage rate my, which is equivalent to assuming that the household receives real income )4 (== w.N)), the amount of which unaffected by the household's choice. So the agent faces the time constraint ll Since barter transactions take time, the transaction time S is assumed as an increasing function of the volume of transactions undertaken (consumption). For a given volume of transactions, the amount of time (and energy) spent is reduced by additional money holding so S is a decreasing function of real money holdingss. Therefore, S, = g(c,, m,_l ) , where m,_l = M,_l /p, and g possesses partial derivatives g3>0, and g5<0, and diminishing marginal effects, gH<0 and gn>0. Since the greater the time spent in shopping, the smaller the amount left over for leisure, it implies that leisure time is a decreasing function in c, and a2 L, . . I I 82L! increaSing in m,.,, 23:—I<0 and ohm >0; 7413—») and 2 <0. I r-l Specifically, it is assumed to take the form of homogeneous function: I“ ll ’ Cr-hmf-l' [ = 1,2, ......... IT (1.3) 0 < a, b < 1 where (1 and l) stand for transaction technology parameters or transactions costs variables. 55 Money' holdings facilitate transactions. It is ‘the real quantity of money that matters. With higher prices, greater nominal amounts of money are needed for given real consumption quantities. The parameter “a” characterizes the time saving aspect of the use of money and may represent the revolution of money and payments technology6. For different definitions of money, the parameter “a” differs. For example, we may reason that the use of fiat money is less time consuming than the use of commodity money, in this case a] > a (.0 Hence, when there is a monetary reform (e.g. from metallic money to paper money), we may observe changes in the parameter “a” to reflect alterations in service flows from a given. real money holdings. We :may also infer that a broader measure of money has smaller “0” than a narrow measure because the former has a large proportion of less liquid assets than the latter. In other words, whenever the agent needs to Hake payment, he has to transfer the less liquid components of his transactions balances into a means of payment first, ‘consequently, this incurs financial transactions costs (costs like in the Baumol-Tobin model), and then reduces the convenience of the use of money. Similarly, for the same definition of money, changes in “a” 6 Saving (1971) deals with the model in a disaggregate manner, deriving demand function for multiple “moneys” (currency, demand deposits, etc.). In this case, the service flow (being a means of payment) from different “money” is not the same because liquidity in various assets differs and this should be reflected in the transaction time function. That is, different parameter “a” for each “money” may appear i11.L. Whereas in our model we consider “money” as an aggregate so the parameter “cf’ may be thought of an index of average service flows from various components of nmmey whatever it is defined. may reflect some regulatory changes or innovations in payments system which alter the liquidity of money over time and in turn simplify (complicate) the payment process7. In other words, for a given volume of transactions, the improvement (deterioration) in payments technology saves even more (less) energy and time by additional money holding. The parameter “b" represents the transactions technology, being determined by geographical factors, or the nature of transactions. For example, we may expect that exchange of goods and services is easier in an economy where the transportation system 115 highly developed than If} an economy where the transportation system is poor. In this sense, we reason that the parameter “b” may change over time due to the development of the transportation conditions in an economy. 7 For example, the automatic transfer from savings to demand accounts (ATS) authorized by depository institutions significantly increase the liquidity of savings deposits, making these deposits serve as transactions balances, consequently, the transaction costs involved in the transfer of less liquidity asset to a medium-of—exchange are reduced. 14 (3) The multiperiod budget constraint To specify the multiperiod budget constraint, we first describe the trading process. Following Lucas (1988), we assume that the agent alternates between portfolio transactions and goods trading in lockstep fashion. At the beginning of each period (t), the agent allocates his nominal wealth (M1,) carried from the end of last period (t-I) into one-period risk free bonds (lfl4) and money (A44), by trading bonds and money in a single centralized market. That is, The bond market is perfectly competitive and the agent is free to borrow or lend at a same rate of r,. Other than bonds, money is tine only asset functioning as ea store of value. The direct cost of holding money is 5,. If 8,>0, the own rate of money is positive; for example, in the modern fiat-money world, deposits in the banking system pay positive interest. 8,<0 may occur in a commodity-money economy in which perishable goods are used as money and its real (and nominal) value diminishes over time, other things 15 being the same. We assume that the agent enters period 1 with a given initial exogenous nominal wealth "38. When security trading is concluded, all agents disperse the money acquired in the portfolio transactions to produce or purchase consumption goods at a nominal price p,. Hence, at the end of period I, the agent's nominal wealth Wfi is W, = (1+r,)B0 + (1+5,)M0 + p,y, — p,c, (1.5) From (1.4) using W0 = B0 + M,,, and W, = B, + M,, we can rewrite (1.5) as Bl + M1: (1+r,)W0 ’ (’1'51)Mo 1’ PIJ’I - Pic: (1'6) Similarly, we generalize the case ”/1 = (1+rI)B-i + (1+8I)MI-l + ply! - plcl I B, + M,, x: 1,2, ..... ,T (1.7) Thus, the bond holding at the beginning of each period up to T+1 is 8 This initial condition allows us to solve the model. 16 By recursive substitution, we obtain the bond holdings at the beginning of period T+1 (8,): i.” l (1+r,) (1+r2) ----- (1+r,._,) (1+r,) W0 + (1+5) (1+r3) """ (1+rT-l) (1+r1‘) PI (yl-ci) + (1+5) """ (1+r7‘—l) (1+r,)p2(y2-cz) + (1+r,._,) (1+ r7.) p,._2 (y7._2-C,-_2) + (1+r,) 1),.I (y,-_,-C,-_I ) + p, (y,.-c,.) - (r,-8,)(1+r2)(1+r3) ----- (1+r,._,) (1+r,) M,, - (r2-82)(1+r_,) ..... (1+’7‘_1)(1+"7-)Mi _ _ — (r,._2—5,._2) (1+r,._,) (1+r,) M,_3 - (rm-67.4) (1+r,) M.,._2 - (r,.-6,.) M,._, - M, (1.9) To obtain maximum utility, the agent has to consume all his nominal wealth at the end of his life T, that is, the l7 terminal constraint (B, = 0 and A4, = 0). Thus, the agent's multiperiod budget constraint at period 1 is obtained by dividing both sides of (1.9) by (1+n)(1+5) ..... (1+rfl,)(l+n) Ply: + szz + pryr O = ”/0 + ..... + (1+r,) (l+r,)(1+r2) (1+r,)(1+r,)----(1+r,) _ __P1_C1__ _ P262 _ _ Prcr (1+r,) (1+r,)(1+r2) (1+r,)(1+r2)----(1+r,.) _ (rt-‘51)mopi _ (r2-62)mlp2 _ ..... _ (rr‘57')mr—1PT (1+r,) (l+r,)(1+r2) (1+r,)(1+r2)--~(1+r.,.) (1.10) (1.10) can be interpreted as follows. 1 Multiplying both sides of (1.10) by (1+n)-—- and rearranging 1 terms, we obtain W (1+n)-;9+ y, + :EI](l+r)4£ly, l II=2 7 I = c, + Z“(l+r)"p' I I==2 T + 0 < o if c, = o, t = 1,2, ,T (1.12) i - amo"'m“- It ( -5 )(1+ " 1+ " 1+ " fink, " I-l pr ’1 I 7“,) ( r2) m( ’7) = o if m,_, > o < 0 if m,_, = 0, t = 1,2,-~-,T (1.13) 1 - 0 at ’ = 0 + 112’:— + szz + ..... _,_ p'l'y’l' (1+r,) (l+r,)(1+r2) (l+r,)(1+r2)°---(l+r,.) _ _Pi_c_|_ _ P252 _ _ pTCT (1+r,) (1+r,)(1+r2) (l+r,)(l+r2)-~-(l+r,.) _(rI-5I)mopi __ (r2_62)m1p2 _ "_._ (rr"5r)mT—IPT (1+r,) (1+r,)(l+r2) (l+r,)(1+r2).---(1+r,) (1.14) Note if r,<5,, that is, bonds are dominated by money as a store of value, money is definitely held whereas no bonds would be held. This is a less interesting case for our analysis. So we assume that r,>6, Vt and investigate the case where a positive money demand is possible even when money is dominated as a store of value. In this case, the 21 only reason for the agent to hold money is to carry out transactions, therefore the restriction M,_, _<_ p,c,, or — S 1 (1.15) must hold. Assuming that {c,};, and {ny,}£, are all positive, we can solve for their optimal values in terms of exogenous variables (demand functions) as follows. To eliminate A and express {c,}£, and {ny,}f in terms I=l 07 of "q, using 6%: == aawg' - A;q(1+n)" = 0 and other first 0 order conditions from (1.12) and (1.13), we obtain q = (r,-6,)m0 (1.16) Note that 0 < b,a < I so (I—ba) > 0. (I) I- I- [1-(78) '13 I p c, = m (r,-6,)(1+r,)(1+r,)----(1+r,)—'m,, l t=2,3,----,T (1.17) Ix) I‘d _ I—l rl—(Sl & In4 — m ( )(1+G)(1+fi)””(l+fi) "q 7,—6, ' I t=2,3, ~,T (1.18) Substitute (1.16)-(1.18) into (1.14), divide both sides by (1+r,)’l and then let "I = P2J’2 P3J’3 PI'YI‘ 1+ W’ + ————— H r') 0 p'y' (1+r,) (1+r,)(1+r,) (1+r,)----(1+r,.)]/p' ”/0 T I ‘1 -| = (1+r,)—— + y. + 2mm.) (I—m y, pi I I=2 we obtain the demand for real money balances at the beginning of period 1: ’ 1 D"W (1 19) m - acz . 0 rl‘ai T-l 7‘~1 ,_ 'l‘ l—(UT where D = [Zfl’+ (a—b)a2w'] = [ '6 + (a-b)0t ]. I=0 I=0 1_fl 1—(0 1 Note that as T—Mt, D = [ + (a-b)a———-] L—fl L—w Therefore, the demand function for {C,}L, and {ny,}£, sequenes are obtained from (1.16)—(1.18) as c,‘ (1-ba)D"W (1.20) c,‘ = [1—(3)"'JB"' (1+5) (1+r3>----<1+r,>£iD"W )6 p. = [1-(£)H]B'-l (1+r,) (1+r,)-"-(l+r,)LDL&~~‘DT’l D"W I6 P2 p3 PT wI-l I-l ' -l = 11%;) 1B [LI(1—zr.)(1+r.)JD W I82 t = 2,3, -,T (1.21) m' =0)"'aa 1 (I+r)(1+r)----(I+r)£'—D"W I—l (r,—5,) 2 3 I pl 1 I =(NTaa' [ U-nfifl+n)]an’ (rI—(SI) 1:21 t= 2,3,"~,T (1.22) where n, = £1:£EL pr 3 Properties of the Money Demand Function From the multiperiod utility maximization framework, we obtain the current desired money holdings written as 0 l _l m0 = aa D W, (1.19) 0"d This can be expressed in the log form 24 ln(m0) = 1n(aaD") - 1n(r,-5,) + ln(W) (1.23) W TI where H7 = (1+q)-;9 + )5 + 2:1](1+n)4(L—fl04}3 and l Ii=2 L—fl’ l-afl D_[1-,6 + (a-b)a,_w] Therefore, the desired real money balances depends on four major factors: (a) the agent’s life-time resources (W’). (b) the nominal return on money (5,) and on the alternative asset (bond) (n). (c) the tastes and preferences of the agent represented by parameters (a,B,w). (d) transactions technology (a,b) To simplify, we write (1.19) as m0 = f(r,,8,;u)W (1.24) where u contains (a,B,w,a,b). From above, a number of properties are in order about this function: First, two rates of interest rates entering the function are one-period rates and no other future rates appear. In other 25 words, given real wealth IV, it is the short-term interest rate that is relevant in this model. The directions of the response of "Q to n and 8, are 5"; a—-—l D"W < o (1 25) = —a ’ 07‘, ("i-(5))2 01"; - aa—L—D"W > o (1 26) 0‘51 — ("1"51)2 . which display usual substitution effect. Second, as in all demand analyses resting on maximization of a utility function defined in terms of “real" nagnitudes, this function is independent of nominal units used to measure money variables. If the unit in which prices and money income are expressed is changed, the amount of money demanded should change proportionately. That is, nominal money demand (M5) function is homogeneous of the first degree in "Q and 1%. As seen in (1.19), the demand for real balances is expressed as a function of “real” wealth independent of nominal monetary values. In particular, nfi is proportional to W’, and it has a unitary wealth elasticity, other things being the same. As Friedman’s (1957) permanent income hypothesis suggests that permanent income is treated as the income flow resulting from a stock 26 of wealth, we define y, = rPV, where r is the yield applicable to wealth so (1.19) can also be expressed as . f(’.,5);u) m0 = -—-r—--y,, (1.27) and (1.27) in nominal terms becomes AL,v = I’ (1.28) [f(r]96|;u) ] -1 . r where v = In this form (1.28) is in the usual quantity theory form. v is (permanent) income elasticity. Third, other ‘than time wealth. constraint and. substitution effect on the demand for money, the tastes and preferences of the agent and the transactions condition also determine the form of the demand function. These effects are summarized by a variable tI== u(d,B,dncI,b). The effect of u may be better examined as that of the issue of the stability of the money demand function. 27 4 Stability of the Money Demand Function The empirical issue regarding the stability of money demand function can be investigated by understanding the preference parameters (0t,[3,d)) and transactions technology parameters (a,b). Note any changes in tastes (U) or the transactions technology (L) induced tax social, political and economic changes can fundamentally change in the specification of U and L and then alter the functional fonn of the Honey demand function, which certainly causes instability of tflua money demand function. Nevertheless we assume 'that 'these functional specifications aux; the same under different circumstances. 131 other words, we ck: not complicate the issue by considering the problem of the Lucas critique (1976). In the following, we consider the effect of the parameters'“a” and “b” (n1 mg. The partial derivatives are computed as an; 1 l-fl’ 1-w" — b D'ZW 1.29 a; ar,—c5,[1—,B 0‘ l—w] ( ) a"; 2 1 (l-w7l)D‘2W > o (1 30) = acz . d7 n-d l—w As mentioned before, changes in the parameter “a” may reflect the shift of the monetary regime (e.g. commodity versus money economy), financial regulatory changes or 28 innovations in payment technology, which in turn affect the costs of using :money' and, then change the desired. money holdings, for a given wealth and opportunity cost. The direction of the effect of the parameter “a” (N1 m5 depends 1—flr_bal—af l—fl l—a) on sign of [ ]; when (l—w)(1-fl") @; a(1-fl)(1—a)")’ a: O< b s 20 Furthermore, a change in the parameter “b” alters "Q in the same direction. Intuitively, when a direct exchange of goods and services becomes harder, the agent is motivated to use a medium of exchange to conduct transactions to reduce transactions costs and therefore hold more money. The effect of transactions costs (N1 the structure of transactions (barter versus money exchange) can be understood. by «examining the relationship between ”Q and transactions c; from (1.16) . aa 1 . = 1.16 "q l—bary—d Q ( ) Define the average amount of money held per dollar of transactions 29 mo aa 1 c, l—ba r, —-(5, As we argued above, (1.15) must hold, that is h .<. I, therefore, aa.<. (1-ba)(r,-6,) (1.31) and 0 S (l-baX’i—6I) a The partial derivative of h with respect to the parameters \\ an and \\ b” are 9'— — a 1 > o 1 32 d2 — l-ba r,—5, ( ° ) fl — ““2 1 > 0 1 33 ab " (1-ba)2 r,—5, ( ' ) That is, the ratio of transactions with money to total transactions is increasing in transactions costs parameters \\ a” and “b”. If payments become easier or barter transactions become cumbrous, the use of money is encouraged in the exchange process so the proportion of the trades 30 through barter are reduced. Note the amount of transactions with money is "n, therefore, (‘ '>—<1 “a 1)‘>o 134 c, m0 — 1—bar,—5, c,_ (' ) is the quantity of transactions via direct barter. Note (1.16) is not a demand function in our model. However, this relationship between desired consumption, the demand for real balances, and the nominal interest rates is frequently studied in empirical work so we also investigate the stability of this relationship. As in time analysis of the “true” money' demand function (1.19), a stable relationship between the desired real balances, transactions variable and opportunity cost variable is determined by the constancy of tastes (a,B) and transactions technology (a,b). Ihi practice, measured income ()M such as CHHU is frequently used as a proxy of transactions variable (c). If transactions and income (or final output) obey ea constant relationship over time, say c, ‘= njq, where n is a constant, (1.16) can be written in terms of y as mO l—ba rl_é-ln)l ( ) 3| Thus, we expect (1.35) has same properties as (1.16). Furthermore, the ratio of money to income, the reciprocal of (current) income velocity, can be expressed as m0 1 aa 1 — n y, v l—baI3—d (1.36) which is independent of income and negatively related to the spread of interest rates, other things being equal. 5 Cash—in—Advance MOdel versus the Shgpping Time.Model Next we compare the transactions money demand model developed ‘by ZLucas (1988) anmi our' model. By assuming a constant relative risk aversion utility function of a homogeneous of degree one function of consumption and imposing a cash-in-advance constraint, I’a c S A4 (Eq.4 in Lucas) (1.37) where 1’ is the price of goods, at and c: are vectors; a. 6 [0,1] is the fraction of purchases of good i that must be covered by money, Lucas (1988) derives a proportional relationship between desired real money balances and consumption 32 A! . 77 = Za,g,(r)c = h(r)c (Eq.15 in Lucas) (1.38) where c = k(Q)W, (Eq.16 in Lucas); Q are securities prices; W’ is wealth. Interestingly, we notice that (1.38) has a similar form to be . _ aa 1 . nq _ l-barq-d q (1.16) in our model. From his cash-in-advance constraint (1.37), we reason that Lucas (1988) implicitly recognizes that barter exchange is possible since However, he does not consider it explicitLy in the nmdel. Hence, by assuming a lcgarithm utility function of consumption and leisure9 (a monotonic transformation of Cobb-Douglas function) and the Cobb-Douglas leisure function of consumption and real balances, our model gives a possible 9 When we considered different specifications of the 1 c"" -1 L1” -1 utility functions, l/(c,,L,) = [ ' -+d ]“’, see l—y l—a l-fl (Mankiw, Rotemberg, and Summers, 1985), the proportional relationship between real balances and wealth (or consumption) is no longer maintained in the model. 33 missing explanation for the existence of his cash-in—advance constraint, namely, the time saving aspect of the use of money. Note the utility function is also a constant relative risk aversion functionuk (mrr model demonstrates that even without imposing that money must be used, we can still generate 23 positive money demand for transactions purpose even when money is dominated as a store of value. 6 Empirical Issues: Arguments in the Meney Demand Function Since an agent cannot hold all the money he might want, in practice, there is the question of the constraint that is imposed on money balances - whether the appropriate constraint is a measure of wealth, permanent income, or current income. In our model, the first two legitimately enter the “demand function” for money, which can be seen from (1.19) and (1.27). Traditionally the use of current income as an argument in the demand function for money often has been associated with the notion that money is used primarily to effect a given transactions volume (Keynes I936, Baumol I952, Tobin 1956, Miller and Orr 1956), and that a demand for cash 10 , , . , —-u"(c,)c, The risk averSion coeff1c1ents are -—;?—;-== 1 and CI —u"(L,)L, —-——-— l. u'(L,) 34 balances depends on costs and yields. In our model, even the money demand function is subject to a wealth constraint, the model is also able to capture this relationship. This can be seen from . aa 1 . m0 = l-ba ’1’5) c, (1.16) This relationship is frequently studied in the empirical work. Interestingly, the desired money holdings are proportional to consumption and negatively related with the opportunity cost variable. Several empirical studies, such as, (Lucas I988, Rasche 1990, Hoffman and Rasche 1991, Stock and Watson 1993, Hoffman, Rasche, and Tieslau I995, Rasche and Hoffman 1996) find a unitary income elasticity and a negative short-term interest effect. These studies find this relationship as a steady-state equilibrium property. If, in addition, in the steady—state c-vty is stationary, then the results follow our model. Thus, this model may help understand these empirical findings. A second issue is concerned with whether a short-run interest rate or a long-term rates is the relevant variable mm the money demand function”. Unlike Poole (1988), among n The importance of this issue can be understood through the following paragraph quoted from Laidler (1966). ‘If investment is more sensitive to long rates of interest and if the first impact of a change in the money supply is on short rates, then in order to have a theory as to how 35 others, who has advocated the use of a long-term in the money-demand function, our model suggests that a short-term rate is the appropriate argument since, given real wealth, no other future rates appear in the function. changes in the money stock affect the economy, one must have a theory as to how interest rates of various terms are interrelated. Thus, -~- the theory of term structure of interest rates comes to be a central topic, essential to any description of the mechanism by which changes in the money supply affect the real variables in.en1 economy.’ (pp.554— 555). 36 III: THE STABILITY OF THE AGGREGATE MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION AND ITS POLICY IMPLICATION Although the Keynesian and Monetarists have emphasized the “demand” side of the economy in their policy prescriptions, they held a different view of the stability/instability of the aggregate demand for money relationship. For example, Keynes (1936) explicitly postulated potential instability in the aggregate demand for money function, which was asserted to shift erratically and unpredictably with rumor and expectations so he doubted the effectiveness of monetary policy”. Keynesian analysis usually treated. monetary' policy' as subsidiary to fiscal policy as EH1 income-stabilization device. (hi the contrary, Friedman (1956) stated that the demand for money was “empirically” stable function of a few arguments. He argued that a stable money demand for money function played a vital role in the analysis of the economy as a whole, such as the 12 Keynes (I936) viewed that money affected the economy through its direct effect on the interest rate, which in turn affected the investment and employment, and finally through the nudtiplier process (if nerginal propensity to consume is less than 1) to affect the aggregate demand and the output (or' employment) However, he doubted that the quantity of money was able to work its way into the economy in the end. For example, the changes in interest rate may be small since the speculative demand for money may shift around due to the expectation of the monetary policy or the investment is inelastic to the interest rate (see Chapter 13, Keynes I936). 37 level of money income or of price. Although he believed that money mattered in the short-run and recognized that manipulation of the quantity of money was a powerful (perhaps dangerous) policy tool, Friedman (1968) doubted the ability of the use of money to stabilize the economy due to both inside lag and outside lag in the monetary policy of a central bank. Consequently, he developed a policy idea of the money-supply growth rule. Although the stability/instability of money demand relationship is not the only difference and would not be the decisive factor which distinguished Monetarism from Keynesian”, we recognize that the stability issue is the central assertion in Monetarism and it is certainly associated with the importance of the quantity of money in the economy. To fix the idea that money matters and how a stable money demand relationship can help formulate monetary policy, as a first step we need to understand the quantity theory of money. 13 In a simple IS-LM analysis framework, how effective monetary policy can depend more than the slope of the LM curve. The responsiveness of aggregate demand to changes in interest rates as well as the direct responsiveness of expenditures to changes in the quantity of money are just as important. A stable money demand function does not guarantee the potence of monetary policy. 38 1 Quantity Theory of Mbney and Mbnetarism The ultimate objectives of monetary policy are to promote price stability and economic growth. The efficacy of using monetary aggregate targets to achieve ultimate policy objective depends importantly on the existence of a stable or predictable demand for money. To put it another way, the velocity of money must be reasonably stable and predictable. From the equation of exchange (Fisher 1911), we know AJV == PY (1.39) in terms of growth rates I! + I’ = I’-+ Y. (1.40) Substituting M“ = M‘], PY V == A!” where A4, Y} enmi.P denote the nominal money stock (however defined), real GNP, and general price level, respectively; V represents income velocity, interpreted as a measure of how much money firms and households desire to hold relative to the level of nominal income. If, in the extreme case where 39 V is constant, as Fisher (1911) claimed, determined. by social and economic factors, or the demand for money is inelastic with respect tx> the variables 1J1 A4“, (1.39) is the model of the determination of money income. In addition, if, in the long-run, the real output (income) is determined by “real” side of economy (factors of production, technology and relative prices) such that output is fixed at full employment level, (1.39) says that the money stock determines the general price level. Keeping the nominal supply on a stable growth will stabilize the behavior of the price level. Friedman (1956) reformulated the quantity theory' by arguing that I’ did not have to be numerically constant over time, but required the stability in the functional relation between V (or the quantity of money demanded) and the variables that determine it. From (1.39)-(1.40), we learn that as long as I’ is predictable or if the growth in the demand for money accompanying a given growth of income can be predicted, the monetary authority can influence growth of money income (aggregate demand) by controlling monetary growth. Inaccurate predictions of velocity growth can lead to monetary targets that are incompatible with ultimate objective. For example, underestimation (overestimation) of the growth in velocity can lead the monetary authority to follow monetary policies that are unduly expansionary 40 (restrictive), resulting in unacceptably high inflation (or recession). The principal of the quantity theory of money is easy to understand through the real-balance effect”; changes in the money stock may result in changes in real output or prices or both in the short-run. The monetary authority can attempt to achieve the short-run output-inflation combination most consistent with its policy objective by influencing the level of aggregate demand (nominal income). However, (1.39) does not tell us how much a change in PY is reflected in Y and how much in P. To infer this, we need to specify all the determinants of the variables associated with (1.39) to capture the complicate transmission from money to price and output which is hidden in (1.39). Economists may have different views of the way an economy works and. then build their own view of macroeconomic models, however, we will not go further about these models, (for the macroeconomic models of Monetarism, 14 Friedman (1974) illustrated time quantity theory (Hf money as follows. ‘Suppose that the nominal quantity that people hold at a particular moment of time happens to correspond at current prices to real quantity larger than the quantity that they wish to hold. Individuals will then seek to dispose of what they regard as their excess money balances; they will seek to pay out a larger sum for the purchase of securities, goods and services, for the payment of debts, and as gifts ----- ’, 'If prices and income are free to change, the attempt to spend more will raise the volume of expenditures and receipts, expressed 1J1 nominal units, which will lead to a bidding up of prices and perhaps also 4l see Friedman 1974, Monetarism, edited by Stein, 1976). We have seen that a stable money demand function is the central proposition of monetarist models. We also observe that this relationship is an important element in the new classical economics models Sargent and Wallace (1975), New Keynesian analysis (Mankiw, 1991), and in some empirical real business cycle models (King, Plosser, Stock, and Watson, 1991) as well. We should note that the monetary authorities may use a dynamic macroeconomic model to compare alternative monetary policies (e.g. pegging interest rates versus pegging monetary aggregates) in order to choose a preferable policy instrument to achieve its policy goal. As Lucas (1976) suggests, in making policy comparisons, it is necessary that the model of private behavior, such as the consumption function, the investment function, and the money demand function, be “structural”, that is, invariant to the policy rule in effect. A shift in the empirical money demand function due to a policy regime shift (or due to other reasons) certainly invalidates these policy analyses. From above, we may realize how empirical evidence against a stable money demand function can invalidate these macroeconomic models and undermine the importance of the monetary policy. In the CHAPTER 3 and CHAPTER 4, we will to an increase in output (pp.2-3, “A Theoretical Framework 42 investigate the empirical evidence of the stability of the aggregate money demand functions in Taiwan over the period of I961:4—1997:3 using various econometric techniques. First we describe the variables chosen for the study of the Taiwanese demand for money in the final section of CHAPTER 2. IV: THE ARGUMENTS IN THE TAIWANESE DEMAND FOR.MONEY FUNCTIONS: DATA DESCRIPTION Economic theories (Keynes 1936, Baumol 1952, Tobin 1956, 1958, Friedman 1956, Miller and Orr 1966, Saving 1971, Lucas 1988, McCallum 1989) suggest that the demand for money can be explained by functional relationships which include a relatively small number of arguments. They can 1x2 a scale variable, such as permanent income, wealth, or current income, and an opportunity cost variable such as a nominal interest rate or some measure of the expected inflation rate. If nominal balances have been the dependent variable, the general price level is also included in the function. Algebraically, the demand for money conventionally takes the form of log linear function ny = jr(y,,R,)-+ p,, f, > 0, j} < 0 (1.41) for Monetary Analysis”, Friedman 1974). 43 where m: is the log of quantity of money demanded; y is scale variable; R a vector of interest rates on the alternatives tx> money; p the log (Hf the general price level. Since economic theory predicts that the demand for money is a demand for “real” balances (money holdings measured in constant purchasing power terms), a price level elasticity of demand for nominal balances is frequently constrained to one. In addition, j" is increasing in y and decreasing in the elements of R. Many empirical studies estimate the specification (m, - p.) = (m,- p.) = f <1-42> (1.42) is empirically referred to the long-run (equilibrium) money demand function which assumes that the observed quantity of real money balances (nt- 1;) corresponds to the quantity of real balances that are desired at the current value of the arguments of the money demand function. It is distinguished from the short-run demand function15 (Goldfeld 15 The widespread practice in the short-run money demand analysis is to add a lagged dependent variable to the equilibrium specification (1.42). Such stock adjustment specifications are motivated by cost minimizing behavior in the presence of quadratic costs of adjustment toward the agent’s long-run demand for money functrmn. In the short- run, some dynamics may appear in the equilibrium specification so that the current money balances can be explained not only by current values of the arguments but also by the lagged real balances and lagged values of the 44 1973, 1976) developed from the partial adjustment model (Chow 1966), see Rasche and Hoffman 1996 for the clarification of the long-run specification, and the criticisms on the partial adjustment models. The choice and the measurement of the variables for the study of Taiwanese demand for money which reflect the corresponding economic notions and time data available are described in the following. 1 Measure of MOney A stable aggregate demand for money function is an important element in macroeconomics, however we do not have theories suggesting the appropriate definition of money for. monetary analysis and particular empirical measures as clearly superior to others which yield more stable money demand relationships. To compare the performance of the money demand functions in Taiwan for alternative definitions of money for the same time period (1961:4-1997:3), we will study four measures of money, namely MIA, MIB, MlBP, and M2. Currently, the Central Bank in Taiwan has three definitions of monetary aggregates, MIA, MIB, and M2, publishing these three series on a monthly basis. MIA and arguments. Hence more general specification of the demand for real balances can be written as m, = f(y,,R,; lagged yr! RI' ml)' 45 MIB are narrowly defined monetary aggregates consisting of currency in circulation and the demand deposits of the individuals and enterprises in the monetary institutions”; they largely serve as transactions balances. M2 is a broader concept of money; it consists of MIB and a large proportion of less liquid assets including time and time saving deposits, foreign currency deposits of individuals and enterprises in the monetary institutions, all the deposits in the Postal Savings System (P.S.S), and others. Data on these three aggregates are available from July 1961 in Financial Statistics Monthly. In February 1997, the Central Bank in Taiwan changed the definition of money, especially in the definition of M2 by excluding less liquid components”, and including new components18 to take account of financial innovations. The data used in our study are redefined monetary aggregates and are retrieved from the FSM data bank of the Taiwan Economic Data Center”. We report the components in the Appendix 1. 16 Monetary institutions are defined as financial institutions which are able to create money (Financial Statistics Monthly, November 1997, pp.190). 17 These include bank debentures issued, savings bonds and treasury bills-B issued by the central bank held by enterprises or individuals and foreign exchange trust funds. 18 They are repurchase agreements and non-resident NT (New Taiwan dollar) deposits. 19 I wish to thank Professor Lee, C.N. for his assistance with the data in my study. The web site address 46 (I) *v v‘ I‘- l). We notice that tine passbook savings deposits 11) the Postal Saving System (P.S.S.)20 are included in.bfl2 but are excluded in MIBZK These postal deposits are also transactions related deposits and are similar to the deposits included in MIB. Furthermore, the amount of this component is nontrivial, around 30% of MIB (on average 1980:12 - 1992:12, see Table 4.2 1J1 (3J0 Lee Ph.D dissertation, Department of Economics, Michigan State University, 1994). A priori we will reason that the aggregation of the same type of deposits may reveal similar money demand behavior of Taiwanese people. Thus, for experimentation, we construct another monetary aggregate (MlBP) by adding these transactions related deposits of the of Taiwan Economic Data Center is http://I40.lll.l.22/moecc/rs/pkg/tedc/tedc2.htm. x) The Postal Savings System is a major financial competitor in the deposit market, competing with the domestic banks for demand and time deposits (Semkow 1992, pp.43-44). According tx> the Central Bank’s compilation of monetary aggregates, the Bank groups monetary assets by the type of institution (monetary versus financial institutions), not by the similar type of deposits. Because the Postal Savings System is not defined as a monetary institution, its deposits are not supposed to be counted in the monetary aggregates. However, in the new definition, all deposits are included in M2 as a non-MIB component. 21 In the study of the equilibrium M1 demand for Japan, Rasche (1990) makes the observation that deposits in the Postal Savings System are excluded in M1 measure which is the most comprehensive measure of transactions money available for Japan. 47 P.S.S into MIB22 to see if this seemingly homogeneous monetary aggregate yields quantitativeLy and qualitatively different conclusions from MIB. The quarterly average series for each monetary aggregate is measured as the geometric average of the three end-of—month observations for 1961:7 - l997:9. 2 Scale variable Whether' the appropriate constraint imposed on inoney balances is a measure of wealth, or income remains an open question. The use of income as a constraint in the money demand function is often associated with the notion that money is used principally to carry out a given transactions volume, for example, (Baumol I952, Tobin 1956, Miller and Orr 1966). The wealth constraint emphasizes the role of money as a productive asset and focuses attention on the equilibrium of the balance sheet, and the allocation of assets and the services that money provides, (e.g. Friedman 1956, Tobin 1958, Saving 1971, Lucas I988, McCallum 1989). The model we derived in Section II suggests that both a measure of wealth and of income are relevant variables entering the demand for money relationship. As in many empirical money demand 22 The aggregate (MIBP) is constructed by the sum of the components with retrieval codes listed in the FSM databank MlBP = MIB + LPSSGSD@TA + LPSS@SD@PSD. 48 .' ~- HI -.. ‘2- '5 'f‘ ~‘\ amv ~~. ¥.. studies, we use real GNP as a measure of the scale variable for the four specifications of the money—demand functionza The data are from the NIAQ databank of Taiwan Economic Data Center. The four measures of money and real GNP are deflated by the GNP deflator (1991 = 100). In the following study, they are denoted as RMIA, RMIB, RMIBP, RM2, and y. 3 Measure of the Opportunity Cost of Holding Mbney Balances The rate of interest entering the demand function is an important variable in a macroeconomic model since it carries the transmission mechanism from a change in the money policy to other sectors in the economy. Hoffman and Tahiri (1994) point out that there is no conclusive evidence as to whether money demand in the developing countries is sensitive to an interest rate measure. Hence, to find.aa theoretically and empirically relevant variable would help us understand the working of the economy in Taiwan and help the monetary authority select an appropriate policy. Conventionally, bank deposits rates (e.g. one-, three-, six- month time deposit rate) are employed as a 23 In the Taiwanese money demand literature, Lyo (1970) used both wealth and real GNP (and unorganized money market rate as an opportunity cost variable) to study the long-run demand for real M1 (currency + demand deposits) and real M2 (M1 + time and savings deposits). The data are annual data (1947-1968). 49 representative of “the” interest rate variable in the study of the ‘money' demand functions in ‘Taiwan. Perhaps it is because of the availability of the data. In Financial Statistics Monthly, the banks rates have longest records (starting 1961:7) and the data (N1 the money market rates, which are frequently used in the money demand studies in the developed countries, are not available until November 1980“. It appears that the choice of “the” rate is underdiscussed in the Taiwanese money demand literature since we observe that some. studies mistakenly treated a proxy of the own rate as the opportunity cost of holding M2. Moreover, a negative coefficient on the own rate is frequently obtained in the demand for M2 studieszs. Shen (1995) first makes this observation but does not provide suggestion of an appropriate measure of opportunity cost of holding M2. This fundamental issue should not be overlooked before we go any further to examine the money demand relationships otherwise interpretations of results can be very misleading. 24 The money market was established in 1976. Note the treasury-bill (TB) market was established in April, 1973 and that the TB rates are available from October 1973 on in Financial Statistics Monthly. 25 See Lin (1997) for demand for M2 function literature review. 50 Since bank rates were subject to the ceiling rates set by the central bank before 1989ufl the structure of deposits rates did not vary freely with the money market condition during much of the sample period considered in this study. They may not adequately capture changes in the opportunity cost of holding money balances. Hence, the market determined rate may be a better measure. We argue that another interest rate should also be included in Taiwanese researchers’ choice list of opportunity cost variables in the money demand study. In the following, we discuss why we regard the own rate of money and the unorganized money market (U.M.M.) . - - 7 rate as relevant variables a prioriz. (1) The own rate on money Since deposits (money) in the commercial banks pay interest and a higher (lower) deposit rate attracts (discourages) the public to hold these assets (due to the same direction of both substitution and income effect), the own rate is a relevant variable in the money demand 26 Interest rate regulation in Taiwan dates back to 1947. Since then, the maximum rates for various kinds of deposits and loans were determined by the central bank (Wu,1995). The process of interest rates deregulation began in 1980. In 1989, the interest rate regulation was totally removed (Semkow Ch.6 I992). 27 A couple of Taiwanese money demand studies employed the U.M.M. rate as a cost variable of holding money (e.g. Lyo I970, Shui 1983, Lin 1997) but little was said about its relevance and its importance. 5] relation. Unless the own rate is close to zero, we should include it in the study to see if the effect of the own rate is of statistical significance. Since all the components except currency and demand deposits in MIA earn non-zero interest and we observe that the interest rates paid are not negligible, which can be confirmed by the constructed own rates in Figure: I, we construct the own rate for each measure of money. The proxy of the own rate for each monetary aggregate is constructed on a monthly basis from the own rates on the individual components28 and is characterized as a short—term rate. The weights are the share of the components in monetary aggregates during the previous month. The own rate on the individual component is from the Financial Statistics Monthly (FSM), listed as “Rates of Banks”. The quarterly rates are obtained from the arithmetic average of monthly m2 . . -h .I, . observations and we denote themII”, I , I”, and I (2) Unorganized money market rate The importance of the role played by the unorganized money market (a curb market) in the financial structure in Taiwan has been emphasized by several studies in the Taiwanese (economic literature (e.g. Pk) I981, Shea I979a, 28 The own rate for time deposits is the average of one— three and six— month “Rates of Banks” listed in FSM. 1979b, 1983, 1986, I991, Liang and Chen 1985, Yang 1984). As pointed out by Wijnbergen in a series of studies for South Korea (1982, 1983a, 1983b, and 1985), the typical financial structure for developing countries is characterized by undeveloped primary securities markets and the existence of the unorganized money market (U.M.M.). This is also observed in Taiwan. Appendix 2 exhibits the source of funds borrowed by private enterprises during 1976-1988 in Taiwan. Due to severely rationed bank credit, the public lends directly to firms via the unorganized money markets, bypassing the banking system. In Taiwan, the private enterprises actively borrow from the U.M.M.29 despite the existence of the organized money market (established in 1976) and substantial reforms launched. to :modernize the Taiwanese financial system in 19805 (see Semkow 1992, 1994). These loans made to the firms are supplied by friends, relatives, and professional money lenders. When looking at the balance sheet of Taiwanese people (private enterprises and individuals), we observe two major monetary assets money (currency anmi bank deposits) and time loans outstanding at 29 Postdated checks are one example of the U.M.M. instruments. They are very popular means of raising funds in Taiwan, especially among small firms. Invoices for goods are stated on the basis of cash payment, but are negotiated into 60 to 90 days postdated check payments, often including rate of interest for the supplier of the purchaser’s loan. The rate is about three times that of money market rate and bank rates, (rate on postdated check = 22.44%, I-month commercial paper rate = 7.86%, October 1997, FSM November 1997). 53 UMM appearing on the sheet30 so that money and loans extended at U.M.M. are gross substitutes, obeying the adding up constraint. On a priori we have reason to regard the U.M.M. rate as tflua relevant opportunity' cost of Iholding money in Taiwan before testing its significance. Finding a statistically significant negative effect of the U.M.M. rate has an important policy message. Wijnbergen (I982, 1983a,b, 1985), by incorporating facts about the financial sector of LDCs (absence of security markets, existence of aa curb merket), analyzes credit policy in 51 macro-model in which the money demand function and the aggregate supply function are negatively related to the U.M.M. rate. He uses the existence of the curb market to explain the empirical observation that monetary policy in the developing countries has effects that differ from what we would expect given.the predictions of the standard macro- model. For example, tight credit policies may lead to higher inflation and less output (stagflation) in the short run 30 It is not argued that there are not other paper assets (e.g. bonds and equities) appearing on the balance sheet of Taiwanese households and firms. The assumption is made on observations, for example, that capital markets in Taiwan are still in the infancy (see Semkow 1994) and most treasury bills are bought and held by commercial banks as liquidity assets (Ch.8, Semkow 1992). So those paper assets may comprise only small portion in their portfolio. Of course, we may observe more varieties of assets held in their portfolio because liberation of financial markets and financial renovation since the 19808 provide Taiwanese people with more financial opportunities. 54 rather than an lower inflation and less output as traditionally assumed because of additional transmission channel of monetary policy into the supply side of the economy via the real costs of working capital (“Cavallo- effect”) other than demand side transmission channel of monetary policy. If this is the case, policy makers should be aware of the adverse effects of the monetary policy documented in these papers and select appropriate measures to offset these short-term macro-economic consequences. The U.M.M. rates are survey data”; The survey was initially conducted by the Bank of Taiwan until 1970:3. The data are available monthly from September 1961 in the Financial Statistics Monthly. In our study we use the “Unsecured Rates in Taipei City” recorded in FSM. However, the series appears inconsistent before and after 1970:3 due to changes in the way of surveying. In order to remove the inconsistency and obtain the longest series for this variable”, the two series obtained in FSM: series 1 (1961:9-197I:2) and series 2 (1970:3-1997:9) are chained at March 1970 in! first multiplying 1961:9-1970:2 data tnl the ratio of the average of series 2 to the average of series 1 31 The earliest records on the U.M.M. rate dates back to May 1947. See Yuan (1986) for detailed research on the unorganized money market rate in Taiwan. 32 Professor Rasche suggested that :U: was problematic to obtain credible statistical results if the sample period 55 during 1970:3-I971:2 and then this adjusted series is linked with the series 2 to obtain the entire series. The quarterly data are arithmetic average of the monthly data, denoted umm. All the data series are seasonally unadjusted. The four real monetary aggregates and real GNP are in logarithms. We plot these series and the spread between the umm rate and the own rate of money (umm—i) in Figure I. The annual growth rates for y, RMIA, RMIB, RMIBP, RM2 and inflation rates (computed from GNP deflator) are presented in Figure 2. Figure 1 suggests that the own rate and the interest spread for each aggregate display similar trend. They peak in 1973 and 1979 when two oil crises occurred and inflation rate climbed up to double-digit. Taiwan does not have a particular high inflation rate over the whole sample period except the episode of two oil price shocks. On average, inflation rate is 5.30% annually. As Figure 2 suggests that real GNP grows at an average annual rate of 8.75% over the sample period and displays the mid-70’s and early 80's recessions common to developed countries. The annul rates of growth for four real monetary aggregates have been very similar 11) one another, both.cn1 a trend and.cx1 a cyclical basis; with the two oil price shocks, four real monetary is too short, especially in conducting cointegration 56 aggregates grow at a negative rate. The average annual growth rates for four measures of money are RMIA 11.59%, RMIB 14.05%, RMIBP 14.62%, and 15.48% for RM2. analysis. 57 Sun .3222. >965 $3553... 3. 2:2". . so ...me _._No. ax....ek....nk . ex _ _B t, ’>\‘ mg 8% (g «at» 3 _ ._ e._.t. | | I I «m sum .56 2. as. 83. 2:: .5 Co 328 2: no. - mo.:.-~o. . ex ..ex.,..nx Oh no v» we . set»...(rI—5lh.rr.bkhp. phpI». 1 I t—! l.‘ (pa 3 I T lllll nva , mvnu .Mon mdfi 33.53 cacao: .o .35. £6 2: ha _..14 _ .ma.t.emo. no No as on as . on um «m “we .2 _ . _ . . .._ iIIIILI.»...vkt.(>>...l.»......LLL....IL..IIII>_ .51.- \ .. (llil . S I | \I .3331 0:3! (.348 , | , up vw m: ow 1| .8852 cacao: a... 3 3.. 2: mart?» C31? LP.” .Linwt r. AMI?» {.mm . p . pg +9.13%}..— I F”? WW re LPN)” .L #er rein!” up 1 06. n.9w Avuw md: 06. - 0d; 7 0d: .50 .5. .o 8.. 2: m6: ESEB mem ..-! 32. ”Sen ecu—coo 3:2: $0533... Co «32 5255 "N 959“. _ 8:38. : 8... .8. . .82... .z. 32... .8. 8 _. . v _ _ _ .. L _ 7 _ _ I _ _ __ b L N3..."— fi ...A.73>».h.37.»..merhbmp_ey»~.rhnrr..I'I*._»I».RIFI>I»WJ.~I».HN‘). e 1 3w! 30¢ . up. u—. N— 2 ca _. 2. 9 .-..._..8.E 3.5.3.198:......~,.Etvi.rr:.£.rimr.imw (11 E O— 48 - ................P.b..._..e....-...ii-...wimir..wi a--. a. or! .32 > e. 2}? 3 +6— (pl 30¢ W 8 .8....1-1...:..mm........+:::1._ :I»L»L>»v...b .vn 3.33:. _P»3.-3~>_»‘__3_~— _L.»%ka.ml.q r3 r2 59 CHAPTER 3 STATISTICAL PROPERTIES OF UNIVATIATE TIME SERIES IN THE DEMAND FUNCTIONS FOR REAL EALNACES IN TAIWAN: 1961:4-1997:3 I: INTRODUCTION The rapid development of time series analysis of models with unit roots has had a major impact on our understanding of the response of economic systems to shocks. It is common practice in macroeconomics to decompose real variables such as output into a growth component, which is associated with real factors such as capital accumulation, population growth, and technological change, and a cyclical component. According to the conventional view of the business cycle, for example, Monetarist (e.g. Friedman 1974) and neo-Keynesian theories, fluctuations in output are assumed. to 1x2 driven. primarily' by shocks to aggregate demand, such as monetary policy, fiscal policy, or animal spirits, and shocks to aggregate demand are assumed to have only a temporary effect on output; in the long-run the economy returns to the natural rate. The time series of real output has a tendency to return to a deterministic path, or to revert toward a trend, following a shock. Since transitory fluctuations are assumed to dissipate over time, 60 a decline in real GNP below trend today has no effect on forecasts of the level of real GNP in the far future. This class of stationary processes is called trend-stationary processes. Many empirical examinations on real GNP using the United States data, for example, Nelson and Plosser (1982) and Campbell and Mankiw (1987), find a great deal persistence in real GNP and are skeptical about this implication, suggesting that shocks to GNP are largely permanent. Instead of modeling the growth component as a deterministic trend and attributing all variations in output changes to the cyclical component, a series whose fluctuations are partly temporary and partly permanent can be modeled as a combination of a stationary series and a random walk (stochastic trend, Beveridge and Nelson 1981). The random walk carries the permanent part of a change and the stationary component carries transitory part of a Changel. Thus, real business cycle models (Kydland and ‘ 1 Any first-difference stationary process can be decomposed as the sum of stationary(x',‘) and random walk Qc3mponent(x,”): Let Ax,= u + c(L)s, , where the roots of C(L) lie outside the unit circle; x, = x‘,‘+ x,”. There are two kinds of decompositions commonly used in the literature: (1) The Beveridge and Nelson (1981) decompositions: x, = *i ‘,‘+ x,", where x,” = p + x,”_,+ C(1)8, and x',‘ = d(L)8,, d,= - ac c,. Note the innovations in x’,‘ and x,” are identical so "i-H. t hey are perfectly correlated. ( 2) An unobserved components model: x, = x‘,"+ x,”, where x,” = H + x,”_,+ r], and x‘,‘ = b(L)5,, E(n,5,) arbitrary. See Nelson 6] Prescott 1982), which attribute a major role to supply shocks in fluctuations of real output, and the traditional view of demand shocks, can coexist to explain the business cycle. In addition, if the output is characterized as an integrated stochastic process, we may question the natural rate hypothesis; aggregate demand shocks may have permanent effects of the level of output as described by models of Inultiple equilibria (e.g. Diamond 1984). From a forecasting perspective, the implication of integrated series is that if fluctuations in output are dominated by the permanent components, the series has a tendency to move farther away from any given initial state as time goes on. Thus a decline in output today lowers forecasts of output into the infinite future. rFrom a purely statistical viewpoint, many statistical procedures rely critically on whether the series is integrated or stationary (including trend stationarity) . The presence of a unit root in its autoregressive representation produces serious problems of statistical inference. Granger and Newbold (1974) find that two independent integrated S'eries can display spurious correlation, characterized by 1”nigh coefficient of multiple correlation R2 and an QNitremely low value for the Durbin—Watson statistic in the \ and Plosser (1982), Cochrane (1987), and Stock and Watson 1988) . Note the variance of the random walk is the same for 62 regression. Phillips (1986) provides asymptotic theory for spurious regressions that relates general integrated random processes. He demonstrates that the usual t-ratio and F significance test do not possess a limiting distribution, but diverge as the sample size becomes large. The use of conventional asymptotics in setting the critical values of these tests leads to the rejection of no relationship at a rate increases with the sample size. In order to avoid the spurious regressions and non- standard limiting distribution of coefficients in the regressions which involve integrated variables and to choose appropriate tests and estimation procedures to study the relationships among the variables, we first need to investigate the nature of the individual time Carefully S eriesj II: UNIVARIATE UNIT-ROOT TESTS A standard procedure of detecting unit roots in a data S:eries is to apply Dickey-Fuller type univariate unit root tests (Fuller 1976, Dickey and Fuller 1979, 1981), or Phillips (1987), Phillips and Perron (1988) unit-root tests. S.‘ane all of our data series in the study are seasonally \ any decomposition of a unit root process into stationary 63 unadjusted, they exhibit substantial seasonality in the levels, especially in real GNP, which can be seen in Figure 1. We should account for the effects of seasonality in the unit root tests. In the literature, three classes of time-series models aare commonly used to medel seasonality: (1) purely deterministic seasonal processes, (2) stationary seasonal gprocesses, and (3) integrated seasonality process (see fiylleberg, Engle and Granger, Yoo, 1990). The use of seasonal dummies variables, as in Barsky and Miron (1989), j.s; not appropriate if the observed seasonality is generated k3}! an integrated process. When applying seasonal difference ffilter, for example, for quarterly data, (I-L‘), as advocated by Box and Jenkins (1970), analysts implicitly )Eissume that there are seasonal unit root roots. Hence Vvithout careful detection of the presence of seasonal unit IToots, the mechanical application of the seasonal difference ifilter is likely to produce series misspecification. IFurthermore, Dickey-Fuller type tests assume that the root C>f interest not only has a modulus of one but is precisely Clne. Such a root corresponds to a zero—frequency peak in the 5Spectrum. In addition, Dickey—Fuller tests assume that there are no other unit roots in the system. The properties of l:3_‘.‘i.ckey-fuller tests in the presence of unit roots at \ C3<3mponents and random walk components (Cochrane 1987). 64 frequency other than zero have been investigated by Ghysels, Lee and Noh (1994). They show Dickey-fuller t-statistics remain valid even when seasonal unit-roots are present if at least three lagged dependent variables are included in the usual regression model. However, the normalized—bias statistic should be divided by four to have the same limiting distribution as that in Dickey-Fuller (1979). To see this, let x, be a univariate stochastic process: >1 II D ‘H l b + "I: N ll ...: N *3 N 1...: where u, is either a stationary process with zero mean and Constant variance or, alternatively, depending on the Context and test u, is a martingale difference sequence following the regularity conditions appearing in Phillips (1987) and Chan and Wei (1988). We can rewrite the time Series in (2.1) as follows: Ax =¢lxl-l+¢2Axl-l+¢3Axl—2+¢4Axl-3+ul I Where¢,=a-land¢,=¢3=¢4=-a. Under the hypothesis that a = I (or ¢, = 0) Ghysels, Lee, and Noh (1994) show the following relations holds: 65 (T/4)$>, —) {W(r)2- 1) / 2f W(r)dr I,I —-) {W(r)2- 1} / 2[£ W(r)2dr]”2 where W(r) denotes a standard Brownian motion on [0,1] . The investigation of seasonal unit roots logically Forecedes the examination of other kinds of seasonality since tests can produce spurious results if seasonal unit roots are present but not accounted for. Our investigation of seasonal unit roots is conducted using the approach developed by Hylleberg, Engle, Granger and Yoo (HEGY) (1990) . This is a general procedure that allows tests for unit roots at some seasonal frequencies in processes that may also exhibit deterministic or stationary stochastic seasonality Without maintaining that unit roots are present at all 8 easonal frequencies . 66 l The HEGY Seasonal Unit-Root Testsz Suppose x, is the series of interest and generated by a general autoregression of the form: where (1-L“) (2.3) 68 It is clear that the polynomial reject the hypothesis of aa unit root at frequency zero for all series. The data reject the presence) of any seasonal unit roots in all of the interest rates except i”. Series y, RM2, and i” may contain a unit root at the biannual frequency (m). 73 Table 1 HEGY tests for seasonal unit roots in quarterly aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances: 1961:4 - 1997:3 Model I: Regression with an Intercept 0 m n/2 Q" Series Lags(k) tI T2 t3 t, p-value y 5 -2.46 -1.79* -2.54** -1.96** 0.22 RMIA 7 -1.36 -2.77** -0.60 -2.79** 0.34 RMIB 7 -1.15 -3.11** -0.32 -3.00** 0.57 RMIBP 7 -I.61 -3.00** -0.33 -3.24** 0.76 RM2 6 -0.98 -1.86* -1.84* -3.20** 0.75 umm-I" 0 -2.13 -8.32** —4.46** -7.40** 0.66 umm-I“ 0 —2.32 -8.41** -4.70** -7.14** 0.66 umm-fir 0 -2.56 -8.51** -4.89** -6.87** 0.61 umm-r"2 0 -1.92 -1.97** -5.47** ~6.35** 0.98 ,. 9 —1.49 -I.60* —0.58 -2.64** 0.99 ,~ 9 —1.31 —2.66** -I.11** —3.05** 0.98 ,M 6 -1.80 -3.42** —I.80* -2.79** 0.52 ,m 2 -2.88 -5.69** -3.31** -0.06 0.93 umm I -2.06 -6.66** -3.75** -6.90** 0.93 Critical Values” 5% ** -2.89 -1.91 -1.88 -1.68 10% * -2.58 -1.58 -I.53 -1.31 An * and ** indicates significance at respectively. (a) This is the marginal significance level of the Ljung-Box Q statistic (1979) for the test of no serial correlation in the residuals of the regression. (b) Critical values are from Hylleberg, Yoo (1990). the 10% and 5% levels, Engle, Granger, and 74 Table 1 (cont’d) Model ISD: Regression with an intercept and seasonal dummies O n m/2 Q Series Lags(k) tI T, t, t, p—value y 5 —2.45 -I.25 -2.15 -2.77** 0.16 RMIA 5 -1.55 -2.72* -I.45 -4.73** 0.21 RMIB 7 -l.08 -3.04** -0.53 —3.86** 0.65 RMIBP 7 —1.54 -3.10** -0.47 -3.91** 0.78 RM2 6 —0.94 -2.17 -l.79 -3.33** 0.58 umm-I" 0 -2.12 -7.95** -4.37** -7.44** 0.77 umm-I" 0 -2.33 -7.98** —4.63** -7.21** 0.78 umm-W' 0 -2.57 —7.97** -4.88** -6.98** 0.76 umm-r’ 0 -1.95 —7.59** —5.49** -6.4l** 0.99 r 9 -1.38 -2.84* -1.35 -4.01** 0.99 r 1 -I.4l -6.54** -4.15** —7.68** 0.20 m 6 —1.75 -3.58** -I.99 -3.20** 0.42 m2 1 -2.84* -6.54** -3.64** -7.92** 0.84 umm I -I.99 -6.66** -3.87** -7.06** 0.81 Critical values 5% ** -2.94 —2.90 -3.44 -1.96 10% * -2.62 -2.59 -3.11 -1.52 75 Table 1 (cont'd) Model IT: Regression with an intercept and a linear trend 0 n n/2 Q Series Lags(k) tI T2 t, t, p-value y 5 —1.15 -1.78* -2.53** -1.92** 0.34 RMIA 7 -l.73 -2.72** -0.65 —2.82** 0.37 RMIB 7 -1.66 -3.03** -0.39 -3.03** 0.59 RMIBP 7 -0.61 -2.97** -0.34 —3.24** 0.77 RM2 5 -3.48** -3.47** -1.96** -1.56* 0.52 umm-i“ 0 -2.26 -8.30** —4.49** -7.38** 0.64 umm-r” 0 —2.35 -8.37** -4.70** -7.12** 0.65 umm-I”r 0 -2.59 -8.46** -4.89** -6.85** 0.61 umm-i"2 0 —2.11 —7.94** -5.49** -6.33** 0.90 r 9 -2.63 -I.57 -0.57 -2.57** 0.99 p 6 -2.49 —3.56** -2.23** -3.15** 0.92 m 6 -1.44 -3.41** -1.78* -2.78** 0.53 H’ 1 —2.98 -6.44** -3.53** -7.69** 0.93 umm 1 -2.24 —6.60** -3.76** —6.86** 0.72 Critical values 1% -4.09 5% ** -3.46 -I.96 -1.90 -1.64 10% * -3.l6 -I.63 -1.52 -1.23 76 Table 1 (cont’d) model ISDT: Regression with an intercept, seasonal dummies and a linear trend 0 n/2 n/2 Q Series Lags(k) tl T2 t, t, p—value y 5 -1.08 -I.24 -2.15 -2.73** 0.26 RMIA 5 -2.47 -2.64* -l.49 -4.45** 0.26 RMIB 5 -2.57 -2.72* -1.56 -4.52** 0.16 RMIBP 5 -1.58 —2.83* -1.45 -4.88** 0.15 RM2 3 -2.72 -2.52 -3.73** -6.00** 0.20 umm-I" 0 -2.27 -7.92** -4.41** -7.43** 0.75 umm-I” 0 -2.37 -7.95** -4.64** -7.20** 0.77 umm-I”r 0 -2.61 -7.92** -4.88** -6.97** 0.76 umm-r"2 0 -2.16 -7.56** -5.52** -6.41** 0.99 p 9 -2.36 -2.78* -1.33 -3.86** 0.99 p 1 -I.98 -6.40** -4.16** -7.34** 0.26 w 6 -I.39 -3.56** -1.98** -3.19** 0.43 r2 1 -2.88 -6.51** -3.62** -7.83** 0.84 umm l -2.18 -6.61** -3.89** —7.01** 0.80 Critical values 5% ** -3.52 -2.93 -3.44 -1.94 10% * -3.21 -2.61 —3.12 -1.51 77 2 The Dickey-Fuller Unit-Root Tests Even the presence of the seasonal unit roots, we can still apply the Dickey-Fuller tests to test for a unit root at zero frequency; Table 22 presents the ‘values of 'test statistics of the DF-t test and normalized bias test. We compute DF statistics based on It x, = ax,_, + Za,Ax,_, + [set of fixed regressors] + .9, Fl where set of fixed regressors are the same as before; k is chosen according the same procedure as described in the HEGY A A test. A t-statistic is based on a, the OLS estimator; Tc(a - 1) is the normalized bias test, where T is the number of the observations, c = (l-Za,)". As we mentioned earlier, in the case of the presence of the seasonal unit root, k should be no less than three and the normalized bias statistic should be divided by four. From the HEGY tests, we observe no seasonal unit roots in any of the interest rates '0 except I , so k is not restricted for the interest rates. From Table 2, the results unambiguously indicate that Y. RMIB, RMBP, and sud. interest rates except V’ and V” contain a unit root, since none of the tests can reject the 78 null hypothesis of a unit root. The null is rejected at the A 5% level by normalized bias tests Tc(a - 1), for RMIA in ISDT, for RM2 in IT, ISDT, for i" in I, IT, and for i’"2 in ISD but not by the statistic for the presence of seasonal unit root, ZSZLD. Thus, the outcome depends on whether these 4 two series have a unit root at frequency m (since we have ruled out m/2, see above). From the HEGY test, the t2 test cannot reject a unit root at m at the 5% level for RMIA in ISDT, RM2 in ISDT, and (I i in IT so we may use KEELD for inference. Hence, the null 4 hypothesis of a unit root is rejected for these series in the corresponding models. 79 Table 2 DP tests for unit roots at zero frequency in quarterly aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances: 1961:4 - 1997:3 Mbdel 1: Regression with an intercept Series Lags A“ t-test Tc(&—1) 7ué-n Q“ (R) a 4 p-value y 9 0.996 -2.20 - 0.47 -O.12 0.25 RMIA 10 0.995 -1.29 - 0.85 —0.21 0.41 RMIB 11 0.997 -l.12 - 0.49 -0.12 0.56 RMIBP 11 0.996 -1.56 - 0.63 -0.16 0.75 RM2 11 0.999 -0.74 - 0.21 -0.05 0.98 umm-I“ 2 0.961 -l.95 - 8.09 -2.02 0.65 umm-I” 2 0.954 -2.11 - 9.19 -2.30 0.62 umm-f” 2 0.944 -2.32 -10.86 -2.71 0.54 umm-I"2 0 0.958 -1.76 - 6.07 -1.52 0.80 r 9 0.936 -2.36 -23.3** -5.84 0.37 r 12 0.982 -l.3l -2.67 -0.67 0.98 w 10 0.978 -1.77 -5.89 -1.47 0.53 W2 1 0.928 -2.92 -10.20 -2.55 0.92 umm 2 0.961 -l.96 -8.52 -2.13 0.77 Critical value‘ 5% ** -2.89 -l3.70 -13.70 An ** indicates significance at 5% level. A (a) a is the OLS estimate of the parameter (a) in the autoregressive representation of the variable, x, = cth, + k EEGQAXF, + [set of fixed regressors] + a. I=I (b) This is the marginal significance level of the Ljung-Box Q statistic (1978) for the test of no serial correlation in the residuals of the regression. (c) Critical values are taken from Ghysels, Lee, and Noh (1994). 80 Table 2 (cont’d) Model ISD: Regression with an intercept and seasonal dummies Series Lags A t—test Tc(&-1) 783-0 Q (R) a 4 p-value y 12 0.995 -2.11 - 0.46 -0.12 0.21 RMIA 9 0.996 «1.40 — 1.04 -0.26 0.21 RMIB 11 0.999 -1.09 - 0.47 —0.12 0.61 RMIBP 11 0.996 -1.56 - 0.61 -0.15 0.76 RM2 11 0.999 -0.73 - 0.21 -0.05 0.94 umm-I" 2 0.961 —1.98 - 8.59 -2.15 0.79 umm-I” 2 0.954 -2.15 - 9.86 -2.47 0.78 umm-W‘ 2 0.943 -2.36 —11.77 -2.94 0.71 umm—r"2 0 0.960 -1.69 - 5.78 -1.45 0.93 r 12 0.965 -1.38 —5.16 -1.29 0.99 r 6 0.982 -1.50 -4.51 -1.13 0.70 pr 10 0.979 -1.76 -5.81 —1.45 0.42 m2 2 0.927 -2.86 -I7.6** -4.35 0.83 umm 2 0.961 -I.98 —8.64 -2.16 0.83 Critical value 5% ** -2.89 -I3.70 -I3.70 8| Table 2 (cont’ d) Model IT: Regression with an intercept and a linear trend Series Lags A t-test Tc(&-1) 7u3-D Q (R) a ‘—7_‘ p-value y 9 0.985 -0.52 - 1.61 - 0.40 0.29 RMIA 11 0.947 —1.90 -20.06 — 5.01 0.47 RMIB 11 0.948 -1.66 —14.89 - 3.72 0.62 RMIBP 11 0.987 —0.54 - 2.40 - 0.60 0.77 RM2 11 0.917 -2.22 -36.08** - 9.02 0.97 umm-I" 2 0.958 -2.08 - 8.92 - 2.23 0.64 umm-I" 2 0.954 —2.14 - 9.40 - 2.35 0.61 umm-I"r 2 0.943 —2.34 -11.06 - 2.76 0.54 umm-I"2 0 0.953 -l.91 — 6.77 - 1.69 0.80 r 13 0.890 -2.42 —36.9** -9.13 0.99 p 11 0.950 —1.69 -12.91 —3.23 0.99 ,» 12 0.979 -1.24 -4.34 —I.09 0.84 m1 2 0.923 -2.92 -I8.39 —4.60 0.92 umm 2 0.957 -2.12 -9.57 -2.39 0.76 Critical value 5% ** -3.45 -21.40 -21.40 82 Table 2 (cont'd) Model ISDT: Regression model contains an intercept, seasonal dummies, and a linear trend Series Lags A t-test Tc(&—1) 7d;_n O (k) a 4 p-value y 9 0.986 -0.49 - 1.54 -0.39 0.25 RMIA 9 0.941 -2.31 -28.40** -7.10 0.28 RMIB 11 0.950 -1.61 -14.05 -3.51 0.65 RMIBP 11 0.987 -0.52 - 2.31 -0.58 0.78 RM2 11 0.918 -2.18 -34.95** -8.74 0.94 umm-I" 2 0.958 -2.11 - 9.50 -2.38 0.79 umm-I” 2 0.953 -2.18 -10.10 -2.52 0.78 umm-VP 2 0.942 —2.39 -11.95 -2.99 0.72 umm-I“2 0 0.955 -I.86 - 6.51 -1.63 0.93 , 12 0.909 -2.36 -21.24 -5.31 0.99 ,. 6 0.944 -2.32 -16.91 -4.23 0.76 ,v 10 0.978 —1.34 —6.02 -1.51 0.42 ,M 2 0.923 —2.91 —18.43 -4.61 0.83 ,»w 3 0.952 -2.31 -10.27 -2.57 0.82 umm 2 0.957 -2.15 - 6.19 -1.55 0.85 Critical value 5% ** -3.45 -21.40 -21.40 83 3 The KPSS Stationarity Tests Several studies have argued that the Dickey-Fuller test, has low power against reasonable alternatives, for example, DeJong et al. (1989) provides evidence that the Dickey—Fuller tests have low power against a unit root near unity. Ghysels, Lee, and rkfli (1994) evaluated. the small sample properties of the HEGY test, finding the HEGY also has low power against the relevant alternatives. Unlike the Dickey—Fuller tests and the HEGY tests whose the null hypothesis is aa unit root pmocess, Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin (KPSS) (1992), propose a test of the null hypothesis of stationarity (short-memory) against the alternative of a unit root. The tests complement unit root tests, such as the Dickey-fuller tests. By testing both the unit root hypothesis and the stationary hypothesis, we can distinguish series that appear to be stationary, series that appear to have a unit root, and series for which the data (or the tests) are not sufficiently informative to be sure whether they are stationary or integrated. To ensure the existence cfifaa unit root at zero frequency, we also apply the KPSS test to the data series. In the study we consider two null hypotheses7; one is the level stationarity' hypothesis” the other is aa trend 7 Canova and Hansen (1993) extend the KPSS test to the seasonal case and propose a test, the CH test, based on the residuals from a regression extracting the deterministic 84 statonarity. The resulting statistics are denoted n”, and n,, respectively. For each test, we will consider values of the lag truncation parameter (q) from 2 to 88. The test results are presented in Table 3 and 4. First we consider the null hypothesis of stationarity around a level. From 'Table 3, VH3 reject the hypothesis of level stationarity for all series except the interest rates (all -n:2 the spreads, 1 , and umm) no matter what value of q we n12 choose. The outcome for the spreads and i and umm depends on the lag truncation parameter (q). Since obvious deterministic trends are present in real GNP and four real monetary aggregates (see Figure 1A, the rejection (n? the null is not surprising. We then proceed to test the trend stationary hypothesis. From Table 4, for all of the series seasonal components and other deterministic components, see Hylleberg (1995). We also consider the regression with seasonal dummies for txflji hypotheses, however, we ck) not report the results in the study because the values of the statistics are almost identical to those in the corresponding regression without seasonal dummies. 3 Since the data series are highly dependent over time and the residuals from the regressions are serially correlated, it is not realistic to assume iid errors under the null and use q = 0, no correction for autocorrelation, in estimation of the long-run variance. The choice of eight as the maximal value of q, is based on the observation that the value of the test statistic has settled down by the time we reach.c1== 8 and the simulation results in KPSS (1992), which suggest q = 8 is a compromise between the large size distortion under the null for l = 4 and the very low power under the alternative for l = 12. 85 except RM2 the null is rejected at either 5% or 10% level for all values of q. For the interest rates, KPSS tests of level stationarity , the ADF-t, ADF-F and HEGY-tI tests of a unit root against level stationarity unambiguously suggest that . .h .h . . . N,z , and 1” contain a unit root at zero frequency Since we can reject the trend stationary hypothesis and we cannot reject a unit root hypothesis. Similarly, combining the KPSS test of the trend stationarity and the ADF—t, ADF—F, and HEGY t.l test of ea unit root against the trend stationary alternative, we find that all the series except RM2 appear to have a unit root at zero frequency. For RM2 and interest I», rates (the spreads and i , umm), since both the null of a unit root and the null of stationarity are rejected, they may be characterized as long memory processes. In the following analysis, hwe will treat them as integrated processes. In order to determine the order of integration maintained in each variables, we apply the ADF-t test to the first—difference of the series. The alternative models considered are again I, ISD, IT, and ISDT as defined above. We report the results in Table 5. From Table 5, we reject the null hypothesis of 53 unit root against all of ‘the alternatives for all series at 5% level. Therefore, we model 86 each of the variables under study in the Taiwanese demand for real balances as an 1(1) process. Table 3 KPSS stationarity tests for quarterly aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances (l961:4 - 1997:3) Model 1: Regression with an intercept Lag truncation parameter (q) Series 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 n”: 5% critical value is 0.463 10% critical value is 0.347 y 3.39** 2.62** 2.20** 1.96** 1.82** 1.73** l.70** RMlA 3.34** 2.58** 2.17** l.9l** l.79** 1.7l** l.68** RMlB 3.38** 2.61** 2.20** l.94** l.81** 1.73** l.69** RMBP 3.38** 2.61** 2.20** 1.96** l.81** l.73** l.69** RM2 3.39** 2.62** 2.20** 1.97** 1.82** l.74** 1.70** umm-i" 0.59** O.46** 0.39* 0.35* 0.33 0.32 0.31 umm-i" 0.44* 0.34* 0.29 0.27 0.25 0.24 0.24 umm-VP 0.34* 0.27 0.23 0.21 0.20 0.19 0.19 umm-1“"2 0.63** 0.49** 0.42* 0.38* 0.35* 0.34* 0.33 P 1.76** 1.37Mr l.l7** l.05** 0.98** 0.94** 0.92** r 2.70** 2.09** l.77** 1.58** 1.46** l.40** l.37** W 1.78** l.38**- l.l7** l.05** 0.97** 0.93** 0.90** rd 0.42** 0.33 0.29 0.27 0.26 0.25 0.25 umm 0.64** 0.50** 0.42* 0.38* 0.36* 0.34 0.34 Test statistics are computed using a Newey-West procedure and the Bartlett lag window as suggested in KPSS (1992). An * and ** indicates significance at 10% and 5% level, respectively. Critical values are taken from Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin (1992) 87 Table 4 KPSS stationarity tests for quarterly aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances (1961:4 - 1997:3) Model IT: Regression with an intercept and a trend LAG truncation parameter (q) Series 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 n,: 5% critical value is 0.146 10% critical value is 0.119 Y 0.62** 0.50** 0.42** 0.38** 0.36** 0.35** 0.34** RMlA 0.31** 0.25** 0.22** 0.20** 0.19** 0.18** 0.18** RMlB 0.26** 0.21** 0.18** 0.17** 0.16** 0.16** 0.15** RMIBP 0.43** 0.34** 0.30** 0.27** 0.26** 0.25** 0.25** RM2 0.11* 0.09 0.08 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.07 umm-i 0.45** O.35** 0.30** O.27** 0.26** 0.25** 0.24** umm-i 0.43** 0.33** 0.29** 0.26** 0.24** 0.23** 0.23** umm-r” 0.34** 0.27** O.23** 0.21** 0.20** 0.19** O.19** umm-r"2 O.46** 0.36** 0.31** 0.28** 0.26** 0.25** 0.25** , 0.24** 0.19** 0.16** 0.15** 0.14* 0.13* 0.13* r 0.42** 0.33** 0.28** 0.26** 0.24** 0.23** 0.23** w 0.64** 0.49** 0.42** 0.38** 0.35** 0.34** 0.33** r2 0.23** 0.19** 0.17** 0.15** 0.15** 0.14* 0.14* umm O.44** 0.35** 0.30** 0.27** 0.25** 0.24** 0.24** See notes to Table 3. 88 Table 5 DF-t tests for unit roots in the first difference of the aggregate series for the Taiwanese demand functions for real balances: 1961:4 - 1997:3 Regression I(with an intercept) ISD(with an intercept and seasonal dummies) Lags t-test Q" Lags t-test Q (k) p-value (k) p-value y 7 - 3.88** 0.38 7 -3.86** 0.29 RMIA 8 - 3.33** 0.07 6 -4.37** 0.07 RMlB 10 - 4.04** 0.61 10 -4.09** 0.60 RMIBP 10 - 4.04** 0.80 10 -4.03** 0.81 RM2 10 - 3.88** 0.98 10 -3.84** 0.94 umm-i" 0 - 8.20** 0.55 0 —7.90** 0.76 umm-i“ 0 — 8.43** 0.52 0 —8.12** 0.75 umm-W‘ 0 — 8.67** 0.42 0 -8.36** 0.69 umm-r"2 0 -10.08** 0.89 0 -9.75** 0.98 ,n 9 - 3.75** 0.16 10 -4.67** 0.99 y 11 - 3.82** 0.98 9 -3.53** 0.81 i» 9 — 3.63** 0.51 10 -4.33** 0.97 in 10 - 4.00** 0.82 10 -4.04** 0.70 umm 0 - 8.21** 0.70 0 —7.98** 0.82 Critical value" 5% ** -2.89 —2.89 See notes to Table 2. 89 Table 5 (cont'd) Regression IT(with an intercept ISDT(with an intercept, and a trend) trend and seasonal dummies) Lags t—test Q Lags t-test Q (k) p—value (k) p-value y 7 - 4.61** 0.20 7 -4.60** 0.15 RMlA 10 - 3.58** 0.40 9 —3.54** 0.19 RM1B 10 — 4.15** 0.56 7 -4.19** 0.60 RMIBP 10 - 4.33** 0.74 10 -4.32** 0.75 RM2 9 - 4.53** 0.98 9 -4.43** 0.93 umm-I" 0 — 8.17** 0.56 0 -7.87** 0.76 umm-1‘ 0 - 8.41** 0.52 0 —8.09** 0.75 umm—W 0 - 8.67** 0.43 0 -8.35** 0.69 umm—i”2 0 —10.06** 0.90 O -9.73** 0.69 p 10 - 4.94** 0.99 10 -4.65** 0.99 p 11 - 3.84** 0.98 10 -4.36** 0.96 ,v 9 — 3.80** 0.45 11 -3.64** 0.77 w: 10 — 4.12** 0.82 10 -4.05** 0.68 umm O - 8.19** 0.71 0 —7.95** 0.82 Critical values 5% ** —3.45 ** —3.45 See notes to Table 2. 90 CHAPTER 4 THE LONG-RUN DEMAND FOR.MDNEY FUNCTIONS IN TAIWAN (1961:4-1997z3): COINTEGRAITON EVIDENCE I: EQUILIBRIUMIRELAIIONSHIP AND COINTEGRATION Economic theories suggest that the long-run money demand relationship can be explained by functional relationships: ml — p: = f(yl’Rl) (3'1) m, p, y, and R are defined as in (1.42). We can write a stochastic version for the long-run equilibrium relationship (3.1) as ml - pl = f1 cointegrating vectors, Wooldridge (1991) shows that OLS estimation. selects time relation. ‘whose residuals are uncorrelated with any other I(O) linear combinations of regressors, also see Chapter 19, Hamilton 1994. Since the OLS estimator has a non-normal limit distribution, which 'involves three parts: a mixture of normals, the unit root term, and the term caused by and quadratic spectral (QS) kernel. As Andrews (1991) shows that QS kernel has the best performance with respect to asymptotic truncated mean square error (M83). 6 Monte Carlo results in Andrews and Monahan (1992) show that prewhitening is very effective in reducing bias, and reducing over-rejection of t statistics constructed using standard kernel heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent (HAC) covariance matrix estimator. 7 Since the test outcomes sometimes depend on the choice of bandwidth (M), the use of a data dependent bandwidth parameter removes the arbitrariness associated with the choice of bandwidth. 99 simultaneous equation bias arising from the endogeneity of the regressors, (Phillips and Loretan 1991). Note that the last two terms produce a finite sample bias (asymptotically the bias will vanish) in median and mean and invalidate the use of standard distributions for testing hypothesis about the cointegrating vector. The inference about the cointegrating vectors based on the smandard least squares output can. be 1misleading. The usual test statistics (t- ratios and Chi-squared criteria) need to be modified to allow for the serial dependence in disturbances from cointegrating errors and endogeneity of the regressors. 4 Inference of Cointegrating Vectors Although the estimates based on least squares estimation are consistent, there exist alternative estimates that are superior. Asymptotically efficient estimation of long-run equilibrium relationship can be achieved by a variety7 of’ methods, for example, full systems MLE (restricted by the imposition of unit roots)(Johansen 1988, 1991), fully modified OLS (with semiparametric serial correlation and endogeniety corrections) (Phillips and Hansen 1990, Hansen 1992a), and leads and lags estimator (dynandt: OLS) (Stock anui Watson8 1993), (for' other 8 Unlike Johansen and Phillips and Hansen’s estimation in which each series is individually I(l), DOLS is developed 100 estimators see an informative review of Phillips and Loretan 1991, Gonzalo 1994). Each of these methods achieves full efficiency in the limit by working to estimate and eliminate the effects of long-run feedback between the errors on the long-run equilibrium relationship and the errors that drive the regressors. These methods are asymptotically equivalent and lead to conventional chi-squared criteria for inferential purposes with respect to cointegrating coefficients. 5 Empirical Study: The Existence of’ the Long—Run .MOney Demand Functions in Taiwan (l96l:4 — l997:3) Since residual-based cointegration tests are developed from single-equation regression models, they depend (N1 an arbitrary normalization of the cointegrating regression. As far as the demand for money function is concerned, the long- run money demand relation with no structural breaks may be written as I I I (ng—ii) ==zz~+ ayy, + czi -+ v Therefore, the natural normalization is to take real balance (m,—p,) as the dependent variable. Without prior knowledge for cointegrating regressions among general I(le) variables with general deterministic components. 101 about whether the two interest rates (the own rate i,, and unorganized money market rate umm) have equal coefficients with opposite signs, for each test we consider two basic models (with no structural break). Model I: the interest rates enter the regression unrestricted lllflfll (m,-p,) = u + ayy, + a,i, + a umm, + [,Btrend]+ v, (3.8) Model II: the spread is used in the regression (ml-pl) : ll + ayyl + durum—I(umml - it) + [mend] + VI (3.9) Relaxing price homogeneity restriction, we find that the tests results from the nominal specifications are similar to those in the real specifications. In Appendix 3, we show that the price homogeneity is not rejected by the data using the t-ratios constructed from the fully modified estimator of Philips eumi Hansen (1990). Therefore, ix) the following study, we only consider the real specification (3.8)-(3.9). In Table 6-99, for each aggregate, we report the Zn and A Z, tests, and the data dependent band width parameter Ad. 9 Although the data are not seasonally adjusted, we do not add deterministic seasonal dummies in the regressions. However, the test results generated from the regressions with these dummies are very close to those in Table 6-9. Besides, the seasonal dummies are INN: significantly 102 The OLS estimates and their standard errors are also presented. Note as we mentioned above, the OLS estimates is a poor candidate for inference, so we should be cautious when using these standard errors to construct t-ratios to test significance of parameters of interest. In the bottom -2 of each table, three outputs from OLS (DW, R and SEE) are presented. Because of its simplicity, the Durbin-Watson statistic (DW) was used by Engle and Granger (1987) to test the hypothesis of no cointegrationuh Although a low DW might be expected as all dynamics are omitted, it should not be too low if the variables are cointegrated. Since the critical values for the test DW=0 are only available for bi- variable system in Engle and Granger (1987)”, no inference is made from this statistic for our three- and four—variable system. We report it just for a quick check if we have a -2 symptom of spurious regression: high R and a too low DW (Granger and Newbold 1974, Phillips 1986). different from zero, individually, and jointly using the t- ratios anui Wald statistics, respectively, which are constructed from FM estimation. Therefore, the results are not reported here but are available upon request. 10 Other than the DW statistic, six alternative tests of no cointegration (e.g. DF, ADF, restricted VAR(RVAR), augmented RVAR, unrestricted VAR (UVAR), augmented UVAR) are also considered in Engle and Granger (1987). l03 (1) The demand for real MlA equation From Table 6, the null hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected at the 5% level by the Z,, and Z, tests only when the regression includes a time trend. It suggests that there is some sort of long-run cointegrating relationship between the variables in demand for real MlA equation. It appears that the time trend is important to the conclusion of cointegration. Comparing test results from.bkxkfl. I and II, we note that these test results do not depend on how the opportunity cost variable enters the regression. That is, two interest rates enter restricted, or the spread is used. From the OLS estimates, we notice that the coefficient on income in Regression (B) and (D) (where time trend is included) is huge. It is not only greater than unity, which suggests that MlA is a luxury for Taiwanese people, but also greater than two, which is rarely seen for the narrow aggregate in the literature. Without the time trend, the coefficients from Regression (A) and (Cs) aux; 1.28, which look more reasonable for this aggregate. Moreover, the coefficients on interest rates are correct. a,n> 0 as the A A theories predict and a,,,,,,,<0 and a,,,,,,,_,-a<0 as we conjecture 11 Note the empirical distribution of the DW statistic in Engle and Granger (1987) is generated without considering a time trend in the cointegrating regression. 104 that the umm rate is a measure of the opportunity cost of holding real M1A in Taiwan. (2) The demand for real MlB equation From Table 7, we find that all of the tests reject the null of no cointegration at the 5% level. The results strongly suggest that there is a long-run relationship between the variables in this equation. The coefficients on interest rates have correct signs and the magnitudes are similar in the regressions with/without a trend. (3) The demand for real MlBP equation Like the demand for real MlB equation, from Table 8 we find that the null hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected at the 5% level by all of our tests. It strongly suggests that there exists a long—run relationship between the variables in the demand for real MlBP data. The signs are correct and the magnitudes of the estimates are similar to those in the real MlB equation. This seems no surprise because MlBP was constructed by aggregating similar deposits in the commercial banks and the Postal Savings System. (4) The demand for real M2 equation From Table 9, we reject the no cointegration hypothesis at the 5% level for all of the tests. It appears that there 105 is also 51 long-run relationship 1J1 this specification fer the full sample period (1961:4—1997z3) in Taiwan. We should note that the coefficients on income are very different in the regressions with/without a trend. From Regression (A) and (C), the income elasticity is about 1.71, which suggests that M2 is a luxury. It becomes less than 1 (0.72) in Regression (B) and (D), indicating that there is economy of large scale in holding M2. Although cnmm<0 as we conjectured, dwa>0, which contrasts with the prediction of theories. Note that adopting' different normalization, that is using )2 as the dependent variabLe, we find that the test results are similar to those in Table 6-9 for each aggregate. .After re-normalizing time obtained. coefficients such that the coefficient equals -l.00, we find that the re- normalized coefficients from the regressions without a trend are close to those in Table 6-9. However, with a trend in the regression, different normalization produces substantially different coefficients. We also test if the umm rate and the own rate on each money are cointegrated. Regardless of normalization, Z, and Z tests cannot reject the hypothesis of IN) cointegration (I occurred between these two interest rates. We report the results in Appendix 4. 106 .OH mfibme mom .aN ocm .N no“ mmSHm> Hmoflufluu mom .mmeHumo coflmmmuomu mo muouuo cumocmum mucmmmudmu mmm .>Hm>fluomdmmu .mao>ma woa pcm mm ecu um mocmoHMHcmHm mmumoHUcH *« ocm + c< ummcmuw cam mamcm CH HH wanna Eoum coxmu mum o u 30 mo mosam> Hmoflufluo one .HOumEHumm cupflzpcmn oflumEouom .Abmmflv cm cam documx Hmuuommm oflumuomsq Umcmuaczmud m mean: commasoamo mum mpmmu am new .N "muoz mmm.o omm.o Hfim.o on wm ma onzo not mmsem> Hmoeufluo Amoo.ov Amoo.ov Amfi.ov Adm.fiv HoH.o Nw.o Hmm.o om.o 44m.vva ¢+mH.mn mao.on vHQ.OI NH.N mm.man AQV Amoo.ov Aao.ov Amfi.ov wHH.o mm.o mmm.o v>.o mv.omu nm.mu moo.on mN.H mm.mn m u . u mmm as v .2 N N ncmuu 3% as: s : iov mumwu :oflumummucfloo mwumeflumw mAO .> + _6cmuun_ + Aka-.essv.wssxoi. :»~: + s u .Nezm "NH Nmuoz Amoo.ov Amoo.ov Aooo.ov AmH.ov Amm.Hv voH.o m>.o Hmm.o >m.o *4N.mmu ++mm.mu mHo.OI mHo.on noH.o HH.N mm.m~n Ame Amoo.ov Anwo.ov Afio.ov Ana.ov PHH.o om.o mmm.o ww.o mm.oma >N.MI moo.on hmo.o mm.H om.mn M— 2 o . mom :0 N- < N N samuu ass at s a fat mummy :oflumuwwucfloo mmumeflumm who ~ . ~> + HocmHUQH + sEEDi-fild + - 3.5 + ~>85 + 5 u .4sz "H anoz (Hz Aden HON nadaiv Geocetwea aw nowueumoucwoo 0: Mom ucwuuoa m OHQQB 107 .0 manna on mmuoc mom NNm.0 00m.0 Ham.0 wofi mm ma 0u30 wow mosam> Hmoflufluu AN00.00 AN00.00 ANH.00 Afivm.fiv m00.0 m>.0 mmm.0 H0.0 siv.Hm| aamo.mu 000.0: nH0.0| 00.H no.0: A00 AN00.00 AH0.00 ANH.00 v00.0 hm.0 000.0 vb.0 440.0vl Nsm0.vl 0H0.0| mm.H v0.0: 5 I Nam 30 m .Q N .N cumuu at as: x : on mummy coflumummuCHou mmumEfiumm who .> + Hccmuuna + AMNI.EssvlT§§N.+. Chad + 3 u .mazm ”HH Hmooz AN00.00 Am00.00 A0m0.0v ANH.00 Amm.flv m00.0 0h.0 m00.0 00.0 ++m.0ml *400.m| «00.0: HN0.0I 0v0.0 m>.H H0.ml Amy A000.00 A0m0.00 AN0.0V AON.0v m00.0 00.0 mmm.0 No.0 ism.mMI ++m0.v| 0N0.0I Nm0.0 mm.H 0m.0| a *2 a . mmm 3o N- .. N N scans as: it A NN A + :98qu + .5223; + ..N ...o + gas + a n .378 "H 3602 ad! HIGH Hon vanadv oeoadtwda aw cowuouuoucfloo on you Ucwueoa b sands 108 .0 manme ou mmuoc mom NNm.o Nmm.o Hem.o Nos Nm NH ouzo MOM mmqam> Hmofiuwno imoo.oc imoo.ov Ame.oc AOV.HV ooe.o mm.o mmm.o Hm.o *.o.mm- ..wo.m- moo.o- meo.o- mo.m am.NH- loo imoo.oc Aeo.ov Ame.oc aoH.o om.o amm.o o>.o ..m.vm- .4mm.v- sfio.o- mN.H 0a.»- 5 I umm 3o m _Q N .N news“ .sa as: s s loo mummu coflumummucfioo mmumeflumw mAO .> + HUcmHUm: + Aahmlsgfii 2.7.55.5 + Chad + D u .mmazm "HH HmUOZ Amoo.ov iqoo.oc Aoeo.oc AaH.ov AVN.HV smo.o mn.o mam.o ao.o ..H.Nm- ::o>.m- moo.o- mNo.o- Gmo.o ma.e om.m- Amt imoo.ov Aomo.oc iso.oc AON.OV mmo.o No.0 mam.o om.o ..m.vv- «:VH.N- omo.o- Nmo.o mm.H am.mn B umm an m .2 N .N 6cmuu as: at s : lav mummy COAumummucflou mmmeHumm 040 .> + 35qu + .52:58 + swan. + $18 + s u 352% "H ammo: mmfiz Heou MOM Uddfldfl onocdlwea cw cowuouuevcwoo on non undueea m .fidnea 109 .0 manna ou mmuoc mom NNm.0 00m.0 HH0.0 mOH mm ma onzo you mmsam> Hmoflufluu . AH00.00 AN00.0V A00.00 A00.00 000.0 Hm.0 000.0 N0.0 N+0.0MI +¢00.vl HN0.0 0N0.0I N>.0 00.m A00 Am00.00 AH0.00 ANH.00 000.0 H0.0 000.0 00.0 s+0.mml +¢00.0I mm0.0I HN.H 0m.>l U I mmm 2o m _2 N .N 6cmuu ANEN Essa x a lot mummy coflumumwucfioo mwumeflumm mqo .> + :35qu + Athn.EEov N....T..=.=.d + Saab + 5 u lmzm n: Hobo: AH00.00 AH00.00 A000.00 Ah0.00 Amm.00 H00.0 00.0 000.0 0H.H 44>.0MI a¢h0.ql 0N0.0 0H0.0I 0H0.0I 00.0 0H.MI Amy Av00.00 AOH0.00 AH0.00 AOH.00 N00.0 00.0 000.0 v0.0 ¢*0.0ml samH.0I vN0.0I 0H0.0I N0.H 00.0I Kw umm 3a _m _2 N .N vcwuu as: New > 2 A40 mumwu coflumumwucfiou mmumeflumm mqo t> + :25qu + .EE:§§5 + $2.16 + 32.5 + s u tmzm "H Hmooz N2. N2 Anon HON Ucdalv Onocelwna cw cowunuueucwoo on non mcwunoa 0 .fidnua 110 (5) Summary From the residual based cointegration test, there is strong evidence suggesting that cointegration occurs over 1961:4 - l997:3 in the variables chosen for the Taiwanese demand for real MIB, real MlBP, and real M2 equations. These results are invariant to the detrending procedures. However, the time trend is important to the conclusion of cointegration for real MlA equation. Table 10 Critical values for residual-based cointegration tests Model I Model II Test 5% 10% 5% 10% Z. C -4.20 -3.89 -3.85 —3.55 C/T —4.53 -4.23 —4.20 —3.89 20 C -31.02 -26.94 -26.00 —22.33 C/T -35.30 -31.02 -31.02 -26.94 Note: Critical values for Z and Z are from Mackinnon I a (1990) and Haug (1992), respectively. 111 III: THE STABILITY OF THE LONG-RUN DEMAND FOR.MDNEY FUNCTIONS IN TAIWAN: 1961:4-1997:3 In CHAPTER 2, we discussed how important role a stable long-run money demand function played in the macroeconomic analysis. In this section, we examine the empirical evidence of the stability in the long-run money demand relationships in Taiwan. From the analysis above, while the conventional residual based cointegration tests in the previous section provide us evidence of a long-run relationship in money demand for real MlA, MlB, MlBP, and M2 in Taiwan for entire sample period, they do not provide us with much information concerning the question of whether or not there is a regime shift in these cointegrating relationships. Moreover, another unsettled issue in time money' demand. analysis is whether the narrowly. defined or broadly defined monetary aggregates yield a more reliable long-run relationship: “under differing institutional arrangements, changes in the social anui political environment aumi changes 1J1 economic conditions” (Meltzer 1963). Lucas (1988) also argues that the demand for money function will be stable over time provided that preferences and trading technology are stable. The following events in Taiwan may play a part in explaining potential changes in the long—run parameters. 112 1963: the New Taiwan dollar was pegged to the US dollar 1973:3-4: the first oil crisis 1976: the creation of the organized money market 1978: the adoption of a floating exchange rate system 1979: the second oil crisis 1980: interest rate deregulation (ending in 1989) 1987: liberalization of the foreign exchange control system 1989: bank entry deregulation With these events in mind, we investigate the stability in these four demand equations for real balances (RMlA, RMlB, RMlBP, and RM2) in Taiwan (1961:4-1997z3). In order to examine the stability in the cointegrating relation and to search for a correct model, we apply the extended cointegration tests with regime shifts developed by Gregory and Hansen (1996) and the parameter stability tests of Hansen (1992b). 1 Residual-Based’ Tests for Cointegration in .Models with Regime Shifts: Gregory and Hansen (1996) Z, and z; Tests In the standard tests for no cointegration introduced iji the jprevious section, it i1; presumed. that the cointegrating vector is time-invariant under the alternative hypothesis: H3 e — I HI e x, — u + a x2, + v, , I I 1,2,”.,n where X3 = (x“,x¢’)' are 1(1) and v; is I(O). In this model the parameters p. and a are cointegrating vector and are considered as tinEwinvariant. Zhi our empirical study (especially for the demand for real MlA data), we wish to entertain the possibility that the series are cointegrated, in the sense that a linear combination (the cointegrating vector) has shifted at one unknown point in the sample; hence, the standard cointegration tests are not appropriate. Gregory and Hansen (1996) extend the ADF, Z', and 2, tests I designed to test the ruflJ.<0f no cointegration against the alternative of cointegration in the presence of a possible regime shift. Such tests can detect cointegrating relations when there is a change in the intercept and/or slope coefficient occurring at unknown date. Rejection of the null hypothesis, therefore, provides evidence 1J1 favor cflf this specification. The principle of testing for cointegration in model with regime shifts is the same as the standard cointegration procedure as introduced in Section II, which is 53 test of unit root in the cointegrating residuals. While the standard testing procedure is to set up the null of no cointegrationf against the alternative of cointegration, the extended tests set the alternative Ihypothesis tx> be cointegration. while 114 allowing for the structural change which is reflected in changes in the intercept and/or changes to the slope. Specifically, Gregory and Hansen (1996) consider three alternative hypotheses. In order to model structural change, we first define a dummy variable. As in Perron and Vogelsang (1992) and Zivot and Andrews (1992), we assume that there is at most one change and we denote the date of break, should it occur, by 1,, with 1 < t, < n, where n is the sample size. Hence, the dummy variable is defined as D(t,,) =lift>t,, I = 0, otherwise. We also define the location of the break fraction 1 = th/n, t 6 (0,1). Three alternative hypotheses of cointegration with structural changes (Hz-H4) are IQ: Level Shift (C) x, = uI + u2D(t,,) I , + d’xm -+ m, t = 1,2. ,n (3.10) This model specifies that there is a level shift in the cointegrating relationship, which is modeled as a change in the intercept u, while the slope coefficients a are held 115 constant. This implies that tflma equilibriunl equation. has shifted in a parallel fashion. u, represents the intercept before the shift, and p2 represents the change in the intercept at the time of the shift. As in Gregory and Hansen (1996), we also denote this model C. It: Level shift with trend (C/T) x11: “1 + uzDIIb): + a'xzr + :6! + V: t = 1,2,“.,n (3.11) In this model, we allow for a time trend into the level shift (C) model. It: Regime shift (C/S) x“ = u,'+ u2[)(n) t = 1,2”.,n (3.12) This model allows both the intercept and the slope vector to shift. This permits the equilibrium relation tx> rotate as well as shift parallel. In this case p, amuiliz are as in the level shift model (C), 0:, denotes the cointegrating H6 slope coefficients before the regime shift, aumi<12 denotes the change in the slope coefficients. We use the same approach described. in ‘the standard residual. based. cointegration. tests, but take account the unknown break date to compute the statistics Z, and 2;. For each possible I (or t,,), we estimate one of the models C, C/T, C/S by OLS, yielding the residuals v”. The subscript t on the residuals denotes the fact that the residual sequence depends (N1 the choice» of change point ‘L. The resulting Phillips’ test statistics for each for each I (or 1,) is denoted Z, (T) and Z0, (1') for each 12 (or t,). The testing scheme is to choose the breakpoint that gives the least favorable result for the null hypothesis of no cointegration; the statistic of interest is the then smallest value of Efiufll of the above statistics across all values of T, denoted by Z, and 2;. In other words, I (or Q) is chosen to minimize Za(T) and Z,(T) for testing that v,r is I(1). As suggested in the earlier literature, such as, Banerjee, Lansdaine, Stock (1992), and Andrews (1990), we apply some trimming such that .15 < I < .85. For our study, the sample size n = 144, so the possible break dates t,,e([22, 122]). 117 2 Hansen (1992b) LM’ Tests for Parameter Instability’ in Cointegrating System The test statistics proposed. by .Hansen (1992b) are designed to test the hypothesis of no regime shift against the alternative of a regime shift. Unlike the tests in the previous section whose null hypothesis is no cointegration, the null hypothesis of Hansen’s tests is Engle-Granger cointegration. Hansen’s (1992b) tests are joint tests on all regression parameters in a cointegrating regression. A statistically significant test statistic i1; taken as evidence against the standard cointegration in favor of the regime shift model. Under the null hypothesis of cointegration, we assume that the generating :mechanism. for AZ: (x“,xh')’ is the cointegrated system x“ = a’xm +-zm (3.13) x2, = Flt + 82, (3.14) A5,, = uz, (3.15) As before 19 = (u“,um')' is p-vector stationary series; the assumption characterizing the innovation vector u, see Hansen (1992a) . (3.13) can be thought of as a stochastic version of the linear long—run equilibrium relationship xh 118 = a'xm with u“ representing stationary deviations from equilibrium. (3.14)-(3.15) is a reduced form which specifies x” as a general integrated process, the outcome of superimposed shock u%(sSt) that influence the process period after period. Since the asymptotic distributions cflf the test statistics depend on the nature of the trends in the regressors x” (Hansen 1992b), as in Section II we estimate both unrestricted model: x“ = u + fl! + a’xh + u“ (3.16) and the restricted model: x“ = u + a’xh +.u“ (3.17) For simplicity, we rewrite (3.13) and (3.14) as x, = A.XD + u“ (3.18) I where JYW = (constant, I, x”). The constancy tests require an estimation of A in (3.18) that has ea mixed normal asymptotic distribution so estimators can be the fully modified (FM) estimator of H9 Phillips and Hansen (1990), the maximum likelihood estimator (MLE) of .Johansen (1998b,1991), or' the “leads and lags” estimator of Saikkonen (1991) and Stock and Watson (1993)”. an3 test statistics using these asymptotically equivalent estimators would. have the same .asymptotic distributions. Following Hansen (1992b), we also consider the FM estimator of Phillips and Hansen (1990), which uses semiparametric methods for serial correlation and for endogeneity. The LM tests for parameter stability are L,., MeanF, and SupF tests”. The three proposed tests are all tests of the same null hypothesis of cointegration with stable parameters but differ in their choice of alternative hypothesis. The SupF test is appropriate to discover whether there is a swift shift in regime, like Z, and 2; which assume a single structural break occurring at unknown date A (I. The other two statistics capture the notion of an unstable model that gradually shifts over time. If the parameter 'variation 1&5 relatively' constant throughout the sample, the L, is the appropriate choice. In practice, all of the tests will tend to have power in similar directions. m Also see Phillips and Loretan (1991) for a review 13 For constructing these statistics, see Hansen 1992b. 120 3 Empirical Study: The Stability' of the Long-Run .MOney Demand Functions in Taiwan (1961:4 - l997:3) In Table 11 - 14, we report the extended tests (ZL,Z,), parameter stability tests — (LC, MeanF, and SupF), the FM estimates, and their standard errors. In each specification, the covariance parameters for constructing statistics are estimated using a QS kernel on residuals prewhitened with a VAR(l) for Hansen (1992b) procedure, and AR(1) for Gregory and Hansen (1996) procedure, respectively. In both procedures, the bandwidth parameter is selected according to the recommendations of Andrews (1991), using univariate .AR(1) approximating :modelshk All of the statistics are computed using the trimming region (.15.85) as in Section II. In the Hansen's (1992b) tests and estimation procedure, we will proceed in a “general to simple” specification search. We first examine the unrestricted regression in which a simple time trend is included and the two interest rates enter the regression unrestricted Un—pfl = u-+a,x +(Li +cx umm,+ flt-+v, I IIIIIIII 14 1996. For details, see Hansen 1992b, Gregory and Hansen 12] Subsequently, we re-estimate the regression by dropping insignificant variables and cmmstraining the tun) interest rates to have equal coefficients with opposite sign if the restriction is compatible with the data. We use the usual t ratio constructed from FM to test the significance of the individual coefficients; and the Wald statistics to test the linear restriction a, -+ a == 0. Under the ruflj. the Wald statistic is distributed as a x2(1). For comparison we present all the results from the un- restricted anmi restricted regressions. However, time final conclusion is drawn from the restricted regression in which all the coefficient are significant. We label these regressions by (A), (B), etc. For each aggregate, the results from the restricted regression, where the conclusion is drawn, are also presented graphically in Figure 3-10, which contains time plot of Z,(t) and Za(t) over the truncated sample along with 5% and 10% critical values for the minimum Z, and 2; statistics”. Figure 11-14 plot the sequence of F statistics along with the 5% critical value for the SupF statistic for the truncated sample. 15 For comparison, we graph all extended tests Z, and Z. even when time trend is not significant. a 122 A t, denotes the estimated break point which is the point in the sample where the smallest value of the test statistic (Z, and 2;) :MS obtained and where the largest value of E‘ statistic (SupF) is obtained. (1) The demand for real MIA equation From unrestricted regression (B) in Table 11, we found that i" is insignificant and has a negative sign, which contrasts with the prediction of the theories. Using DOLS estimation (Stock and Watson 1993), the coefficient has the correct sign inn: still insignificant, with/without ea time trend in the regression”: RMIA, = -16.24 + 2.38)¢ + 0.13i”, - 0.02umng - 0.02! + v, (6.79) (0.61) (0.23) (0.01) (0.01) RMIA, = - 3.88 + 1.27y, + 0.141’", - 0.01umm, + v, (0.63) (0.05) (0.26) (0.01) Dropping i", we rewestimate regression an. In regression (D), all coefficients are significant at either 5% (n: 10% level (the critical values of the t-ratio i1; 1.65 for 5%, 1.28 for 10%) and have correct signs (the time trend is 18 The leads and lags in the DOLS estimation are included in the regressions but their coefficients are not reported here. negative from data information). Therefore, the conclusion from test results are based on this regression. In regression (D), all three stability tests L,, MeanF and SupF are not rejected at the 5% level, implying this long-run relationship remains stable over the whole sample period. Hansen (1992b) discovered that the L, can be regarded as a test of the null of cointegtration against the alternative of rm) cointegration since the lack of cointegration is aa special case cfif the alternative hypothesis (an unstable intercept) where the intercept follows a random walk. Since all of the parameters appear stable, including the constant, this implies that the null of cointegration hypothesis is not rejected. From Panel B of Table 11, we can see that the null hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected at the 5% level by z; and 2: tests only when the regression includes a time trend (the C/T formulation). We should note that although the null is rejected by z; and 2, tests, providing evidence in favor of C/T specification (Eq.(3.10)), we are unable to conclude from these two tests that there is ea structural break. The reason is that the alternative hypotheses .Hg-ffl (Eq.(3.10)-(3.12)) in the extended tests contain as a special case the standard model of cointegration with no regime shift, a conventional cointegrated system with 124 constant parameters could produce results of cointegration from these extended regressions. Using the umm rate alone, we' also conduct. the standard. cointegration. tests Z,(= — 5.80**) and Za(= -53.80**), finding that the null of no cointegration is also rejected. Turning to the FM estimates in Regression (D), we notice that the income elasticity (1.86) is huge as the OLS estimates in Table 6 and significantly different from unity. As we mentioned earlier that this is rarely seen in the literature for this narrow aggregate. The estimates obtained in the regressions without a time trend Regression (A), (C), and (E) are more reasonable. The conclusion of cointegration depends on the detrending procedure and it appears that the linear combination of the I(1) variables under study reverts to a trend. However the significant trend gives us difficulty in interpreting time results. Firstly, economic theories only suggest that (ny-zL) -df(yg,R ) should have an equilibrium, I that is, the discrepancy should not contain a trend. Moreover, to accept this long—run relationship, VH3 need a reasonable explanation for a huge income elasticity. Balancing the evidence we have obtained, we doubt this equilibrium relationship. We notice that the test results and coefficients from the regression (F) in which the spread is used are very 125 close tx> those from regression H” where the tumn rate is used. Finally we present the test results 2:, and 2; fer C, C/T, and C/S (Panel B in Table 11) graphically in Figure 3- 4, and the sequence of F statistic from Regression (D) in Figure 11. We can see that the sequences of Z,(T) and 20(1) for C/T regression cross the 5% 2' and 2; cxitical values I several times, suggesting rejection of the no cointegration. The sequence of F statistics for structural change is well below the 5% critical value, indicating the parameters are stable. (2) The demand for real.MlB equation From the unrestricted regression (B) in Table 12, the estimated coefficient of V and the time trend are not significant at the 5% level, which is also robust to the DOLS estimation, so we re-estimated regression by dropping them. In Regression (C), all of the coefficients are significant at the 5% level and possess correct signs. The following analysis is based on Regression (C). The Inn. MeanF and SupF tests cannot reject the null hypothesis of a stable cointegrating relationship at the 5% level. As in the analysis of demand for real MlA, the L, 126 test implies that the hypothesis of cointegration is not rejected. Turning to the 2; and 2: tests (Panel B in Table 12), the null of no cointegration is rejected at the 5% level for all of the tests (10% for the C formulation). It is consistent with the L, test, suggesting strong evidence of cointegration among real MlB data. Again, the 2; and 2: tests do not provide us with much information about any shift in this relationship for the reason we mentioned in the analysis of the demand for real MlA. Using one single interest rate, umm, we compute the standard cointegration tests as Z,(= -5.80**) and Za(= —53.80**). Hence the null of no cointegration. is also rejected. We note that the stability tests results are robust to the regressions we used; the only test which rejects the null at both 5% and 1% level is the L, test in Regression (A). This suggests that this long-run relationship among the variables we chose is quite stable over the sample period. This result contrasts with that in Lee (1994) who finds a downward shift in the demand for real MlB around 1982:4. In Regression (C), the estimated income elasticity (1.56) is significantly different from unity at the 5% level so MlB is a luxury to Taiwanese people. The interest semi— elasticity is around - 0.015. Using the sample mean value of umm rate (24.12%) to convert the interest semi-elasticity, we obtain the interest elasticity is of the order of —0.36. Constraining cy.==‘-amm, which is not rejected by the Wald statistic, and then using the interest rate spread, we find that the test results and estimates in regression (E) are similar to Regression (C). Finally we present the test results 2:, and 2; for C, C/T, and C/S graphically (from Panel B in Table 12) in Figure 5-6, and the sequence of F statistic from Regression (C) in Figure 12, along with the critical values. (3) The demand for real.MlBP equation From the unrestricted regression (B) in Table 13, we find that the time trend is not significant, which is also observed in DOLS, so we drop it and re-estimate Regression (A). The coefficients in Regression (A) are all significant at the 5% level and the signs are consistent with we predicted. Thus we interpret the results based on Regression (A) in the following. All of three parameter stability tests reject the null at the 5% level, casting some doubt about the existence of a stable long-run relationship in this specification. All 2; and 2: tests (from Panel A in Table 13) reject the null of no cointegration at the 5% level in favor of the structural break specification. As we mentioned, this monetary aggregate is obtained by grouping seemingly' homogenous deposits ix) the commercial banks (MIB) and in the Postal Savings System (passbook savings deposits). Since we have shown that the demand for real MlB displays considerably constant over the same sample period, the instability in this equation may arise from the behavior’ of ,postal saving deposits. After examining the graphs of data series (RMIB, RMlBP, and interest rates) in Figure 1 for these two equations, we found that the trend and cycle of two data set exhibit similar pattern over the whole sample period. Casual inspection of the time series provides us with little information about the possible source CHE nonconstancy. However, parameters instability in the demand for real MlBP may be explained by the difference in. liquidity' characteristics ill MIB eumi passbook. savings deposits in the Postal Savings System. J.C. Lee (1994) finds that the annul turnover rate of the demand deposits in the Postal Savings System is significantly lower than those in the commercial banks”. Deposit holders seem to “regard” the deposits in the commercial banks to be more liquid than I7 The turnover rates Emu: year‘ for 'various deposits are: 2.9, and 0.7 for passbook savings deposits and time deposits in the Postal Savings System, respectively. 200 for checking accounts, EM) for‘ passbook. deposits, and 20 for 129 those in the Postal Savings System even though there is no substantial difference in the easiness to convert the deposits into a medium of exchange. This indicates that these postal deposits on the average are not being actively used for transaction purpose, and they may be more like investment balances or savings vehicles to deposit holders, therefore, their behavior may be influenced by wealth, for example, instead of a measure of transactions (real GNP) or other factors. Thus, the specification for this monetary aggregates might not adequately capture a stable money demand relationship. To summarize, the existence of cointegration in this specification is problematic. This specification appears subject to a structural change and may not be correctly specified. The sequences of Z,(t) and 20(1) (from Panel A in Table 13) in Figure 7 and 8 indicate that there is a well—defined minimum from these six tests. The smallest statistic is obtained roughly at one third of the sample (1:0.34, Ih=73:3); the break date coincides the first oil crisis. In Figure 13, we plot the sequence of F statistic for the restricted Regression (A). passbook savings deposits in commercial banks, J.C. Lee (note 9, Chapter 9, 1994). 130 (4) The demand for real M2 equation From the unrestricted regression (B) in Table 14, each of the coefficients is significant at either 5% or 10% A level. However we notice that (Ln ‘< 0, which is frequently obtained :hi the studies of time Taiwanese literature and A contrasts with the prediction of the theories. (mm ‘< 0 is also observed in the estimation of OLS (Table 9), DOLS, and Johansen's procedure with/without a trend. Based on Regression (B), the null of cointegraion with constant parameters is rejected by the I“. test, MeanF and SupF at the 5% level. A stable long-run relationship in the demand for real M2 is doubtful. The negative coefficient on the own rate seems to signal this instability. Because of the instability occurred in real MlBP equation instability for this equation seems no surprise. Since this specification may be subject to a structural break, it may not kme correctly specified. Before i1; is re-examined, we cannot provide any explanation for the negative own rate coefficient in this study. It needs further research which is beyond the scope of this study. Note the results of instability are robust tie the detrending procedure, which can be seen from Regression (A). 131 'r‘ I! L) I T (D The sequence of Z,(t) and 20(1) for (L. CWT, and C/S (from Panel A in Table 14) are presented in Figure 9 and 10, and, the sequence of F statistic for regression in Figure 14. (5) Summary From the analysis above, it appears that the narrowly defined monetary aggregate (M1B) yield more reliable long- run money-demand relationship in Taiwan in spite of several potential regime shifts over the whole sample period (1961:4 - 1997z3). The broadly defined monetary aggregates (MlBP, and M2) do not provide evidence of a stable long-run relationship; the specifications in our study may not adequately describe the “true” money demand behavior for these two aggregates. Moreover, the most stable long-run money demand relationship occurs in the demand for real MlB. The time trend is important to the conclusbmi of a stable long-run demand for real MlA function; however, to accept this relationship, one need to provide a reasonable explanation for a huge income elasticity. One the one hand, that M1B yields most stable money demand relationship (mu) be justified tn; the transactions- demand theory, with money held as a medium of exchange. The real quantity of money demanded is an increasing function of some measure of the volume of real transactions (real GNP) 132 and a decreasing function of the opportunity cost of holding money (umm or the spread). On the other hand, the demand for broadly defined money (RMIBP and RM2) might be associated with the portfolio and speculative demand, with money as (Mme of several possible assets in which wealth may be held. Thus, instability detected in these two aggregates is explained by misspecification. That is, the resulting money demand depends on *wealth rather than income (the proxy of ‘the volume of transactions) and some measure of the volatility of alternative assets’ returns in addition to their expected returns. However, we leave this conjecture unanswered in our study. 133 HvubmH Hm">00 Hmnmwg Hmnan Hmnnma _mum>0 NN.0vI eem.mnn mm.amn mm.v| e+0m.mu em.mn m\o H\U U m\u H\U U ”N ”N memos acaumu0oucfloo comcmm ocm wuo0ouw HHHNmH “000.00 A000.00 Amm.00 Amm.vv 00.0 N0.0 0r.0 NH0.0| VH0.0| 0m.H rm.0Hn A00 HHHN00 AmH0.ov “00.00 AH0.00 +emm.>H va.0 4400.N «H0.on 0N.H >0.m n boom memo: .q ocouu ES: x 2 A00 mumou wuflaflnmum comcom moumEHumo Em .> + 20:98.3 + .5536 + Ciao + s n ..373 .m Hocmm HNHNNH .muhmi _muom0 .Nn>m_ .Nuemi _muom0 0.0v1 eem.nnu 00.Hm1 vm.m| eemm.>1 m0.vn m\o B\U U m\u H\U U ”N ”N mumou cofluoumoucflou comcm: oco wuomouo HmnmmH ”000.00 A000.00 A0mH.00 mom.00 A0v.m0 mm.o 0N.NH Hm.m 44mm.m NH0.0| m~0.0| 0v0.0| 00.H No.0HI Amy Hanvng AOH0.00 Amam.00 “00.00 Amm.00 mH.0 4+0.0H 0m.> 44mm.v NN0.01 000.01 0N.H m0.mn .55. ... 6A0 n 5 + 50 “Ymmz mmsm memo: .4 Ucouu ES: am > 9 Adv mumou Nuflaaomum comcom moumeflumo Em .> + Zucouum: + .Esszsao + c ...d + .>Ad + s u Julia 5‘ Hocmm 33 52 ion "apnea hoceuecou uouoauuan van «amaze eawuou saw: memo» cowueuuoucwou 3 can...“ 134 .mooam> Hmoflufluo MOM 0H10H oanme oom .sc ucHOmeouo ooumEHumo one ouo H 0 CH mousoflm .Ho>oa 00 one so unmoflwflcoflm moumoflonfl 4* .>Ho>fluoodmou .Ho>oa 00H new 00 now HN.N one v0.m oum AHvNN now mooam> Hmoflufiuu ”Amy ouoz Hvunmi .muan aquamn Hwaan Hmnwmg anemn 00.0mu *ev.0nn 00.0NI N0.v I «+mm.>n mm.mn m\o H\U o m\U &\o o ”N ”N mumou coflumumoucfloo nomcm: Ucm Nuomouw HHHNmH A000.00 A000.00 Amm.00 Amm.vv 00.0 Hm.0 00.0 m~0.ou 0H0.0| 00.H m0.0Hu nmv HHHN00 Ameo.00 n00.00 nm0.00 +¢>0.0H 0H.0 e+mn.m «H0.0| mm.H 00.m I . ~1EE: scam mcmoz N scouu . a. s : Ami mumou xuaaflnmum comcm: mouoeflomo Em s> + :25qu + an»? :55: .7555 + 31.6 + z n .dazm "U Honmm Av.vcoovfifi CHAIR 135 .Ho>oa 0H onu um unmoflwflcmflm no: me .0 “H ouoz HHHPmH .vn000 ”mumm0 Hmnnmm Hvu000 Hm“m>0 +40.m01 ++H.00n www.mvt «emv.0n 4e00.0u e+mm.0n m\o m\o U m\u H\U o “N ”N mumou noflumumoucfloo comcmm Ucm wuomouu Hm"000 A500.00 A000.00 A0m.ov nmfl.v0 00.0 mm.v Nv.0 000.0: >H0.0| 00.H H0.0Hu n00 HmuvhH A000.00 Amo.ov nqv.ov 00.0 0H.m 0>.0 0H0.0| 00.H 00.0 I mmsm mcmoz .4 econ» as: m 3 A00 mumou xuflaflomum comcm: moumeflumo Em .> + Honouum: + CEE:..=..=5 + Cwao + s n .022 um Hocmm Hanmmm HHn000 .mummm HH“>00 Hv"00_ ”muomm 00.001 *40.001 0H.>v1 mamm.0n e400.0| ¢+H0.0| m\o 9\U U m\o H\U U ”N ”N mumou coflumumoucfloo comcm: Ucm Nuomouw HVH>00 A000.00 A000.00 AN00.00 Amm.00 Am>.mv No.0 0v.HH 0m.> _+e0m.fi 000.0: NN0.01 000.0 N0.H 00.01 Ame HHHV>0 AHH0.00 nv00.ov ”50.00 A0m.00 0H.o 00.0H 0H.0 4+0>.H vmo.on m00.0 mm.H Nv.0| .55. .. an0 n d +.NJ“VHm3 mmsm mcmoz .A Unouu ES: am > : A<0 momou Nuaaflnmum comcmz moumsaomo 2m .> + 5503 + ~.EB.........5 + 0.18 + :28 + s u .25 ZN 3:3 0 33 as: anon Henna» huaecoo Hence—ewe.“ van names» 0500.» saw: mama» coaueuuoucwou NH .Hanenr 136 .HH mHQMH. Ou mquE mmm Hmuan mvummm .mnms0 Hmnhmm 4vnmmH Hmumnm *40.00l 4&0.m0l *00.vvl ¢e0H.0I eemm.0l ##HN.01 m\o e\o U m\u B\U U ....N .N mumou noflumnmounfloo comco: Ucm wuomouo Hmu000 4000.00 AH0.0V 400.00 AHH.vv N0.m 00.m mv.0 000.01 No.01 N0.H 00.0 I 400 HNuv0H AOH0.00 400.00 40v.00 00.0 0H.m 00.0 . 0H0.01 00.H H0.0 I mmsm mcmoz .4 Ucouu AsunEESV > 3 Amy mumou mu444omom comnm: moume4umo Em .> + 29533 + £7.53 ......58 + :18 + a u .35 no 388 AU.HQOOVNH CHAIR 137 .44 o4ome ob mono: oom 4mn>00 44nvnH 4mnm00 4munmn 44nvhi 4m meg 44N.00l +4v.00l 440.00! 4+0N.0I 44NN.0I 4+v0.0l m\O H\U U m\u H\U u .NN ..N mumou c04um40oDC4oo comcm: ocm muomouw 4mu000 A000.00 A000.0v n00.00 “40.00 00.04 00.0 4404.4 000.0I 040.0I 00.4 00.44I A00 44u000 A040.0v n00.00 40v.0v 40.04 04.0 4440.0 000.0: v0.4 00.0 I . NIEED mmsm mammz q 6couo s. 4 2 ion mumou mu444nmum comcmm moboe4umo 2m .> + 44:5qu + 4307 255: 2.7.5.35 + C446 + s M .00420 ”m 49.80 44uaan 44uv>n 4mnm>n 44us>m 44uv>m 4muman 440.401 440.001 44v.m0l 4*00.0I 440m.0l 4400.0! m\o H\U U m\o B\U O ...N ”N memos c04umumoucHoo comnm: Ucm Muo0ouo . 44um00 A000.0v 4040.00 A4v0.00 A0m.00 n04.vv 4440.0 4404.vm 44N0.0N 4404.0 000.0 .000.0I 004.0 mm.4 00.NI n00 44H000 A440.0V A000.0V nv0.00 A00.00 4V4.m 4400.00 4400.04 440v.m 000.0I 000.0 00.4 44.0I IEE. «4 . a A0 I o + 4 50404003 mmsm mcmoz 4 ocouu ES: $4.4 0 5 SN: mumou N44444mum comcmm 4ncmuuan + W®UMEHUWW Eh .EEsssao + 0.4.215 + 3446 + o N 00420 "d 4950 33 m3: 18 ”queen honeymoon wovoauwdm van eumwse Qaduou and: name» cowuuuuoucwou ma .Hflnua 138 40"00_ 44u000 44u000 400000 44n000 44u000 #4m.0wl 0.0VI 440.00I 4400.0! +4Nm.0l 4440.0I m\o 0\0 U m\o 0\U U 4N ..N momou c04um40ouC4oo comcmm Unm Euooouo 40u000 4v00.00 4v00.00 A04.00 n04.00 00.44 40.0 4400.4 000.0 000.0I 00.0 40.v 400 44ummn 1400.00 nmo.ov mom.oc 0v.04 440v.04 440v.4 000.0I 00.4 v0.0 I mmsm mcmoE .4 Unonu EE: 0 5 400 mumou 0u444omum nomnmm moumEHDmo Em .> + 498.34: 4 .522248 + .048 + s n .078 "0 4980 400000 4vu000 4vu000 40u000 4vu000 4vn000 +4©OHI +40.0ml 440.mml £400.0l i+vw.ml 44mm.0l m\U 0\U U m\U 0\U U ”N ..N mumou c04um40oun4oo nomcmm UnMINuomouo 40"00_ nv00.00 A000.00 4040.00 404.00 n00.40 44v0.0 4440.00 4400.0 4400.0 000.0 .040.0I 000.0I v0.0 40.0 A00 44u000 1000.00 0000.00 nmo.ov 140.00 4400.0 444.004 440v.04 4400.0 000.0I 440.0I 00.4 00.0I §§ I. =40 n 5 +4 ovade mmsm mcooE .4 Ucouu ES: NEW 0 s 4 4 49$qu + .85: — d + .Ncso + Ni. 3.6 «r anon ~>kd+gu moomE4umo Em .020 "m 4wcma Henna» avenuecoo Houefluuem van evMHSe Qawuou and: nueou cowuauuoucflou v4 .104ea. 139 .44 o4om0 Op mouoc oom 40H000 4vn00m 4vu000 44H000 4on000 4vn000 440.00I v0.0vn 440.00I 4400.0I 00.0I 4400.0I m\U 0\U U m\U 0\U U ”N ”N mumou c04uo40ouC4oo comcmm Ucm muomopo 4mummn 1400.00 1000.00 104.00 iom.Nc 4440.04 4400.0 4400.0 000.0 040.0I 00.0 40.0 nmv 40H000 4000.00 A00.00 400.00 4400.00 4440.04 4404.0 000.0I 40.4 00.0 I Q . A ~IEEDV \A m :0 mcmoE 4 pcouu . Ni. 5 Amy mumou ED444omum comcm: .> + 495qu + 44.....4I.EE:0 2.1-256 + C446 + : moumE4umo Em I .020 no 4mcmm 46.9cOOVVH CHAIR 140 Table 15 Critical values for z; and 2; tests m = 3 m = 2 Test 5% 10% 5% 10% Z? C —5.28 -5.02 -4.92 -4.69 C/T -5.57 —5.33 -5.29 -5.03 C/S -6.00 —5.75 -5.50 —5.23 22. C —53.58 -48.65 -46.98 —42.49 C/T -59.76 -54.94 -53.92 -48.94 C/S -68.94 -63.42 -58.33 -52.85 Note: n1:hs the number of I(1) regressors. Critical values for 2: and 2; are taken from Gregory and Hansen (1996). Table 16: Critical values for L,, MbanF, and SupF, tests m = 3, p = l m = 2, p = 1 5% . 1% 5% 1% L, 0.90 1.29 0.778 1.13 MeanF 9.21 12.00 7.69 10.3 SupF 19.3 23.9 17.3 21.4 Note: m is the number of I(1) regressors; p: the power of trend in the data. Critical values are from Hansen (1992b). 141 IIIIIIIIIII iIIII IIIIIIIIIiIIIIIWHQF.“ -Eouez um\o n-30: Adm} <22 .3. .8 Ease. 9: .2 4.25:2..." EN to sea as: "N 2:9". B 828 5.12. k. 3. 2, I an 8 .1441 00 0 00 00. 00, .00 00 I'||l"|'l|l|ll|l"l|| 4‘.LI_E4EIEI.[[4L . £5 2:33. "90 .28: 0.0- T Q N. 0.0- 0.0- 0.0. 0.1. 0.7 :unsramz 0.0. 0.0- r “N. 0.0- .3 8. . .B 8. r8 .5344. R. 2 4.x... I... 3 N I. 40454bvuf-4r. .rLI. 7.)..- tnupo I _ uxtth» . 0 .I teeth 5.3 5.3 .243 ”to .0303 5:0 .25.. H0 .0433 0.?- I . 0.0. 0.?- . 0.1. . m.”- - o4”- .. 0.0- 0.0- 0.4. 142 <22 .3. .8 2.25.9 05 .8 3.503» EN .0 .0... 08.... "v 950... F0 00 II .[| ...... it . 5.3 l ” 3-3 - I _ o (N I :3. 3.0.0 5 00 .00 00 .00 _F0 00 .00 00- 0'- 55 2.33. .20 .38. 07 3 00. 00 00 .00. .3. .00 00 00. 00. —0 00. 0o _DLI..Ir.Ill.[r.|J-..lr; _._... . ...-yr...(it......Li-L...‘....t~.....t.lL.I-f .. I... {-8 I .8.-G - | _ .55 ll 0:2... 5.3 5:0 .254 “to .030! p w m m. 0 :4 00 00 p bah»)h—bghribmlrphiamr-DEwE.rJML-L>°Pb 5...?!» 0? D’L‘thrhf- >>PLV5F>L>w ..- ... 8333 WI): .....m .23 6 .28: 80 00- 53 0w. ans-(3)2 143 ms... .8. .o. 25% 2.. .2 8.5.3.... an .o 6... we: a 2.5... 00 00 .0 . .00 00 00 00 .0 00 00 ......»- ae.u.¢ "m6 is: 0.0- 3 00 00 00 .00 .5 .00 00 .00. .00 F0 00 00 .- L . .-. . . ....I.I-_I-.:.y...i: ...CLL».I.§......I>-...{L:...-ELIIFIL 0.9 town I ~ .8. 5 - I 0-..; I. -.. - 0.0. I no- I | I. II III II ||||| I ’ I | llllll 0.0. 0.7 0...- ..5: 5.... a...» .2... Eu .28: rpm. La.£78100»...mmgrflym..trmm£mmtrtfi.?.mrfl rtrm-ertr-Gwmtl-Lkhro . “NW- .SHu I .8. u - ..- 1.0.0:“.- .- 8.”- . 00.7 a...» .26.. no .88. . 00.!- MR was-(3)2 144 as...” 09:.va “wxlol .6305. {ulna .IiIlu ..nU 0'30: m :2 .3. .0. 052.80 2: .0. 3.5.36 EN .0 3... 2...... .0 0.30.... 0000 ’H 0?.‘5’P—I'LLII ......z..m.o....fi........... ..fi. ..00....m».....m....._.......: . H _ . _ . . ... ......m 2:53. 5.3 .8.. EN Inn-garb.........wi...u...s....m.-...............»r-m....-.m».,.:......._.._.m....0m r .....m 2.3:. .20 .28... Inc-(I): ...» n . 8 5 ’h P5 PbbwiL’flgrmm.v>rmth>$Er . h t»? ‘FthtthDF. II ..- 00- 0:20 5.3 G...» .03 ”to .808 B 3 8....5...m0...........5.mms_m...s.....0..._.o......:...0.m 0.0V- Egmg H0.000! 0. 00.. ans-(I): use-(I): 145 .9... .8. 3. ucasoc 9.. .o. 8.6.5» ...N .o .0... we: a. 2.5... 00 00 00 0.0 :00. —0 .00 00 00 00. _.—0 .00 00 8-: I 8-: - I . \. UZI. £20 2.3:. 5.3 =3 .3 ..a.ImmI¢..mE..o...é .8...,........-..»...00....m0-....n.....:..........._......_....,...o. 5.8 I _ .8.-mu - I ” mQQN I f -ll'l'lI-Il'l"ll-|l1l II|I"III a...» 25...... "m6 .8.... 0.0- 0.0- 0.0- 0.0- 0.0- ...... 0.1- 0.?- 0.0- 0.0. 0.0- 0.0- - 0.0- .. O6- 0.?- 0.? ans-(v2 ans-(1)2 to... .3......-.50.:...-.0..-.mm......n.......00.5%.. .m L&~u> III. 0 pm 8 00 >>—.. .. p .r>»>—.r» E?&.p>btmmr>rhuarm ytthbfmwkbrh.smP .LI?>F>F.I 00 .3 00 gnu I town - I .33I; 29.05.300.303)... “3.0003 4" £30 .25... "0 .000! 0.0- . 0.0- 0.0- 0.0. tun-(3)2 0.0- .. 0.0. . 0.1- 0.?- 0.0- 0.0- .. 0.0- n 090 0.0- 0.1- 0.?- 146 mm :2 .mm. .o. 0:08.... a... .0. 3.30mi EN ..o .20 «E... .0 2:0... L.» .r7>.0L .IpL0Vru ufifh II. In . . >pb..|_...>..y ......L.-.—LL.P 8.18.»... 3 8 . 3 ...». .R. ...... a... .5 .8. .8 ......m 25.5. 5.3 .815 00 00 00 00 00 00 0.. 0. 0V... 0» IFL b > P . rLL...0L5.P».IL.n>pvk.u>—05>FVL..—LLrerLb- vrtprsr. LuphLML {h rg hr-‘rII; ......» ......5. ”m6 .8.... 00- NH"! 0000 '0 .>>.p..L.»»>.L. 0 uPEEELLLL LL imrimh :0 Frat» :LI "LthFLmLLI—LL. IL... .kafm HI. ...I 3| WU)? 0:8... 5.3.03.0 .25.. ”.20 .0003 .....j . .....m...mo.....n.~.£r...........K...r$.:rfi.:.m0.....r....._3.:r..m '0‘: - ION”; lv-l" U I I Ins-(U): £30 .25.. Ho .0003 147 NE .99. ..o. cam—:2. w... .5. mozmzfim EN .0 .0... 08:. ”m 959“. =32 a: .... 22:8 a- ...... garage ...... ..$..m?$- ...LRRP a... (....u | .830 I I I. _ . o. T 8...... _ f 8...- I N. n r 8.? - .. m 1. .. 3.1. Y m- r 8.? , Y r 8d. a. . cad. 8.2.5 2:38. 5.3 .3. EN 9.2... 5.! .....m .25.. .....o .803 wr’erLFB» L..NlrfrhImmI.swunLLG...rrr.m.th.°rmLr>..Lh{_f...umeLLthLm:r»Lm»:L.G.M..L.hr.°t_ |.l11 °.°l —LF.L._L:_3.:.LN:°~:L..nmL:~:£:>p.mmpur—Lo.»>tbh$...—merrbmmL.LLFLLKJ.>>._LG..m—:L.b:°_ 0.0! 3.0 II #26 I I u..~ I r 09 x r..- O.”- 7 Oh! I as. m I n6. W 3. I 3. I ad. I on- 0.9 IIIIIIIIIIIIIIII I IIIIII r on- ad. we? at...» 2:301 ”90 .83! 5.5 .0)... "U .35! 148 us. .02 ..0. cam—=00 0;. ..0. 83030.» EN .0 .03 08:. 5.. 0.59". .hmhhnm 5. an unfmw an .F .3 so. A \ f 3,.» \ \ z/IIKI’II) /( \ 3:5 2:53. 5.3 .8. EN . , _ .6, an .3 .3, .8 .5. ..fi .fi m... .2. ..., .8 B ...:m 2:301 "m6 .235 NIH-)2 Ins-(I): -18. , B- 8. 9 m - 0.1 - 3- 8- 3. ...—Bk 5.... .....m .05.. "to .35! .5 .8. .8. .3. .8. .8. ... ... .2. .2. .... .3 .B. 8- -3 -2.n m .3 -8. 0V ..Em _0>0._ un. .08! 149 32...... 2 ...... . .. .-.”... ...... .8. . a we on .n N2 .3. .0. 000500 .0. .3. "...—...... 22...... 8 B. .8 .8 .... .... ... .... .2. . ... 3. ... ..m .... =2 a. use... a. .8. ..am "I'd «.23.. S 8 .5. .3. .8. .... 2, .... .... n. .. 8 .... . . . . ...: .3. 3. 2.an 3. .8. .95 52.3.. 5. 8 B .3. .8. ... .2. .... ...... .2. .F .8. .o _ . . . S... .8. 3. 2.2.8 .o. .8. ...:m n.5— W’d ms 150 IV: JOHANSEN’S FULL INFORMEIIONIMAXIMUM LIKELIHOOD ESTIMATION I Introduction From 'the residual based cointegration tests in the Section II and III, we have found evidence of cointegration with stable coefficients between the variables in the demand for real MlA and real MlB equations. However, we cannot determine from those tests whether the cointegrating relation is unique or whether there are other linearly independent cointegrating vectors in the system. Approaches other than residual-based tests for cointegration are available, for example, the likelihood ratio tests of cointegration rank of Johansen (1988b, 1991), Johansen and Juselius (1990), and a common stochastic trends test proposed by Stock and Watson (1988). Such tests developed from systems methods enable researchers to avoid invalid restriction from arbitrary normalization in the cointegrating regression of the residual-based tests”. Ebr example, the variable on the left hand side of the regression may not appear in the cointegrating relation at all, but a unitary coefficient is wrongly imposed on this variable. These tests also have the advantage of testing for the number of cointegrating relations. Since the Johansen 19 Conflicts may arise in empirical work where the test outcome depends on the normalization selected. U] (1988b, 1991) maximum likelihood methods for the analysis of cointegration can simultaneously detect the INflMKH? of the cointegration rank :Ui the system, estimate and test for linear hypothesis about the cointegrating vectors and their adjustment coefficients, we will apply them to continue our study of long-run money demand equations in Taiwan. Testing for the number of cointegrating relations and estimating the cointegrating vectors starts with ea VAR(p) representation expressed in first order difference and lagged levels where x, :hs a p-dimensional vector of I(l) variables; D, are centered seasonal dummies which sum to zero over a full year and where 8,, ------ , 8,. are IINP(O,A) and x_,HI ------ x0 are fixed. The H matrix conveys the long-run information in the data. The hypothesis of 1: cointegrating vectors is formulated as a reduced rank of the HFmatrix H2(rd: 11 = aB’ (3.20) where a and B are pxr matrices of full rank. 152 Under H2 (r): Hi: aB’, (3.19) can be interpreted as an error correction model (see Engle and Granger 1987, and Johansen 1988a). 2 Empirical Study: The NUmber of the Cointegrating vectors in Taiwanese Money Demand Data (1961:4 — 1997:3) We apply Johansen’s maximum likelihood method tx> the study of the long-run money demand relations (MlA and MlB)20 in Taiwan. For a comparison with the results in the previous sections (II and III), we consider both 4-dimensional VAR (where x = (m,y,i,umm)) and 3-dimentional VAR (where x = (m,y,umm-i) for the basic model for each money-demand relation, where m denotes the log of real balances. Since the intercept vector (uo) can be decomposed into linear trends :hi the data and intercepts in the cointegrating relationship (Johansen and Juselius 1990, Johansen 1991b) and the trend coefficient p, can be decomposed into quadratic trend coefficients in the data and linear trend. coefficients 1J1 the cointegrating relations (see Osterwald-Lenum 1992), the assumptions about the properties of the trend and linear restrictions about no 20 We also consider the order of the cointegration rank for the other two aggregates (MlBP and M2). We cannot reject the hypothesis of no cointegraion (r=0) at either 5% or 10% even 20% level from the trace and max-A tests. These add more evidence against ea stable long-run relationship for 153 and th are important in distinguishing the correct asymptotic distributions of the test statistics. Since all of time variables except for the interest rates are characterized as I(1) processes with drift, we estimate all of the models under the assumption of a linear trend in the I(1) variables. Specifically, (3.19) without a time trend and centered seasonal dummie521.is fitted to the Taiwanese demand for real MlB data Model I: H2: Ax, = rlel-l + """ + rk—leI-IHI + an—k + “o + 5: (3.21) Because the time trend_ is crucial to our conclusion of cointegration with stable parameters for the demand for real MlA data from the single equation methods, we also consider model (3.19) under the assumption of the existence of linear trend in the cointegrating relations (but the absence of quadratic trend) to take into account of a significant these two aggregates. We do not report the results here but the results are available upon request. “ Although our data are not seasonally adjusted, *we do not include the centered seasonal dummies in the model, because the results obtained in the regression with seasonal dummies are similar to those we report in the text. In addition, from the fully modified estimation we found three seasonal dummies are not significant either individually or jointly for each demand for money equations. 154 linear trend in FM estimation”. That is, under the null we estimate Model II : H; = IUILE4 4. ...... + FLJAXHMJ + a(B',Bl)(xhl',t)’+ uO-+ q (3.22) (see Osterwald-Lenum 1992). The lag length (k) was chosen as the minimum length for which there is no significant autocorrelation in the estimated VECM residuals using the Ljung-Box Q statistics (1979). The misspecification tests for normal iid assumption for the residuals in the model are reported. The normality assumption is tested by the Jarque and Bera statistic (Jarque and Bera, 1980). (I) The Taiwanese demand for real MIA data (A) Misspecification tests The misspecification tests for the model are reported in Table 17. For the two data sets (three- and four— variable), the choice of k renders the residuals white noise. However, there are indications of excess skewness and kurtosis in the residuals of the interest rate equations, causing the Jarque—Bera test statistic to become ’2 Explicit inclusion of a linear trend in the cointegrating relations implies that there :hs some linear growth which our model cannot account for given the chosen data set. 155 significant. We conclude that the residuals from RMIB and y can be assumed to follow a Gaussian process, those from interest rate equations follow an innovation processZ3. (B) Testing for reduced rank For VAR(4), Model I (3.21) is fitted to the data“,- for VAR(3) we consider both Model I and II (3.22). From Table 18, the trace and 1mm tests fail to reject r = 0 at either 5%‘ and 10% level even 20% level (significant at 20% for VAR(4)) for all of the model we considered. Since the time trend is important to the conclusion of cointegration with stable coefficients from the residual based tests (Table 6 and 11), the inability to reject Pa in VAR(3) adds more evidence against the hypothesis of cointegration with constant coefficients among the variables in the. demand for real MlA. Using a single interest rate, umm, we reach the same conclusion of no 23 The deviation from normality is not a serious problem. As long as the cumulative sums of errors converge to a Brownian motion, the asymptotic analysis gives the same results as those under the assumption of normality (see Johansen 1991b, Johansen and Juselius 1992, Gonzalo 1994). 24 We also consider model II under the assumption of a linear trend 1J1 the cointegration relations. Although the trace and AW tests reject r = 0 at the 5% level, the estimated income elasticity and interest semi-elasticity are perverse, having wrong signs enui being economically A meaningless. (AMAJflnrfl.,,..,..r/3.> = (1.00, 12.28, -5.08, - 0.28, —0.28). l56 cointegration which also differs from the conclusion we reached in previous sections (II and III). Table 17 Residual misspecification tests VAR(4) with k = 8, x = (RMlA,y,i”,umm) Eq. S.E.E” Sk” BK” r,“ Tz‘~ x2(34) ARMlA 0.03 -0.33 0.14 1.97 34.18 Ay 0.01 0.21 -0.04 0.77 37.44 A?’ 0.05 0.37 5.37** 132.37** 45.76 Aumm 0.58 1.06** 3.51** 75.62** 23.22 VAR(3) with k = 5, x = (RMlA,y,umm-i”) Eq. 5.3.3 Sk EK Tl 12~ x’(34) ARMlA 0.03 -0.14 0.26 0.70 42.00 Ay 0.02 0.13 -0.03 0.36 42.56 Aumm-r' 0.66 0.89** 5.19** 150.39** 26.78 Note: a. S.E.E (denotes the standard_ error' of regression estimate. b. SK and EK are the skewness and kurtosis statistics. A ** indicates the test of the null hypothesis that each is zero is rejected at the 5% level. d. The Jarque and Bera test for normality (Jarque and Bera, 1980), I, = T—n1 2 EK2 S 6 ( 4 ) ~ x2(2), where m is the number of M ,3 regressors. C. The Ljung-Box Q-statistic T(T+2)[§:7,Ij), .hl ‘ where r, is the jth lag autocorrelation of the residuals. M is the number of autocorrelations used, and is selected according t1) the formula D4 = ndn(T/4,3T2),. with aa maximum value of 36. H7 Table 18 Tests of the cointegration rank Panel A Model I: VAR(4)' with k = 8, x = (RMlA,y,i",umm) ‘33 fit!) It)" 10"“7' H2 eigenvalue trace/ ma r = 0 0.131 41.90 19.07 r S 1 0.095 22.83/ 13.51 r S 2 0.041 9.31 5.74 r S 3 0.026 3.57 3.57 Panel B Model I: VAR(3)2 with k = 5, x = (RMlA,y,umm-i°) H2 eigenvalue trace Am“ r = 0 0.092 23.92 13.41 r S 1 0.055 10.52 7.94 r S 2 0.018 2.58 2.58 Panel C Model II: VAR(3)2 with k = 5, x = (RMlA,y,ummri”) H; eigenvalue trace 1m“ r = 0 0.107 30.12 15.67 r S 1 0.064 14.45 9.25 r S 2 0.037 5.20 5.20 Note: 1 Model I: Ax, = FIAxP,-+ ------ + I“,,_,Ax,_,‘+l +IH x“, + pa + s, is estimated. 2 Under the null of cointegration rank = r, Model II Ax, = rt Axl-l +""+ rk—let-k+l + “(B' 1B1) (XI-l, ,t) ' + “0 + 8: is assumed. See Table 23 for critical values. 158 To conclude the cointegration analysis for the demand for real MlA, we represent the normalized eigenvector associated with the largest eigenvalue and the corresponding weight in Table 19. We notice that the coefficients in panel (c), under the assumption of a linear trend in the cointegrating relation, the obtained income elasticity is not only greater than unity, is also greater than two, as mentioned above, which is rarely seen in the literature for this narrow monetary aggregate. The time trend is important to the conclusion of a stable cointegrating relationship in the demand for real M1A from single equation methods (Section II and III). To accept this conclusion, we need to accept the huge income elasticity. Based on economic theories and all the evidence we have obtained as well, we conclude that there is no such long-run relationship for the demand for real MlA data. 159 Table 19 The eigenvector associted with tho largest aigonvslue (v.) and the corresponding weights (uh) Panel A (RMlA,y,i”,umm) Model I: VAR(4)l with k = 8, x = m y i” umm A 1.00 -1.27 -0.76 —0.014 V1 (0.21) (0.27) (0.17) (0.008) A 0.01 0.05 0.03 1.15 “’1 Panel B Model I: VAR(3) with k = 5, x = (RMlA, y, umm-i“) m Y umm-i" A 1.00 —l.26 0.003 VI (0.14) (0.24) (0.26) A —0.10 0.001 1.36 WI Panel C Model 11: VAR(3)? with k = 5, x = (RMlA, y, umm-i") m Y umm-f' t A 1.00 -2.33 0.019 0.023 V1 (0.04) (0.42) (0.008) (0.009) A -0.13 0 01 0.83 WI See notes to Table 18. computed using the Figures in ( ) are standard errors procedure suggested by Johansen (1991). I60 (2) The Taiwanese demand for real MIB data (A) Misspecification tests The misspecification tests for this model are reported in Table 20. As in the demand for real MlA data, the normality hypothesis is rejected for the interest rate variables U*,umm,umm-W) chm; to excess skewness and kurtosis. Thus, the residuals from. real RMlB and. y are assumed to follow a Gaussian process and the residuals from the interest rates follow an innovation process. Tabla 20 Rasidnal misspecification tests VAR(4) with k = 7, x = (RMlB,y,ih,umm) Eq. S.E.E SK BK t, 12 712(34) ARMlB 0.03 -0.28 0.81 4.18 29.73 Ay 0.02 0.13 -0.03 0.30 53.06 Ajb 0.09 0.47** 3.26** 51.80** 31.32 Aumm 0.63 -0.72** 4.07** 84.04** 21.30 VAR(3) with k = 5, x = (RMlB,y,umm-i") ARMlB 0.03 -0.25 0.72 3.85 45.82 Ay 0.02 0.09 -0.08 0.19 41.09 Aumm-fl' 0.65 0.85** 5.20** 149.61** 26.61 Note: Model Ax, = f,Ax,_, + ------ + l",,_,Ax,_,,+1 + H x,_,, + 110 + s, is fitted to the data. 16] (B) Testing for reduced rank From the trace and Am“ test results in Table 21, the null hypothesis of no cointegration (r=0) cannot be rejected at either 5% or 10% level for the two data sets. However, the null is rejected at the 20% level, which appears consistent with the results from the residual-based cointegration tests (see Table 7 and 12). Although the acceptance of one cointegration vector in the system relies on the test size of 20%, which usually would be considered too high, Johansen and Juselius 1990 suggests that when the cointegrating relation is quite close to the nonstationary boundary, the powers of the test are likely to be low. Hence it seems reasonable to LHKB a higher critical value higher than the usual 5%. In order to make final decision of the order of the cointegration rank, we also examine the stationarity of the cointegrating relation 03x,) constructed from. the full- sample point estimates. The ADF-t statistic (= —2.64 for VAR(4), = -3.22 for VAR(3)) (using 9 lagged differences) rejects the unit root hypothesis at the 10% level for VAR(4) model, at the 5% level for VAR(3), suggesting that the cointegrating relations for these two data sets are stationary. Since we reject r = 0 and we cannot reject the hypothesis of r S 1 at 20% level, we conclude that there is 162 only one cointegrating vector between the variables in the models. Note in APPENDIX 4, we show that there is no cointegration. between lumn and. W. Thus, we rule out the possibility that this cointegrating relationship comes from these two variables alone. When using the umm rate alone, we obtain similar results as those from the model using the spread. Therefore, the result is consistent with the conclusion we drawn in Section 111. Table 21 Trace and km“ tests VAR(4) with k = 7, x = (RMlB,yyib,umm) H2 eigenvalue trace Am” r = 0 0.116 40.45 16.84 r S 1 0.095 23.60 13.73 r S 2 0.052 9.87 7.26 r S 3 0.019 2.61 2.61 VAR(3) with k = 5, x = (RMlB,y,umm-V) H2 eigenvalue trace Am“ r = 0 0.095 24.60 13.91 r S 1 0.057 10.69 8.23 r S 2 0.018 2.46 2.46 See note to Table 20. See Table 23 for critical values. 163 Next. we report. the :normalized. cointegrating 'vector25 and the error correction coefficients in Table 22. The standard errors of the normalized cointegrating vectors are obtained using the procedure suggested by Johansen (1991). We will use the obtained point estimates and their standard errors to test the significance of each regressor. For the VAR(4) model, the signs of coefficients on income and the own rate are consistent with the prediction of the theories and both are significantly different from zero. The sign on umm rate is consistent with an conjecture that the umm rate is a Heasure of the opportunity cost of holding real MlB in Taiwan, however, it is not significantly different from zero. Since the constraint (,6, = -,6,,,,,,,,)26 cannot be rejected by likelihood ratio test (LR = 1.37), so we reestimate the model. We find that not only that the interest rate spread is significant, but also that the trace test turns out to reject the r‘== 0 at the 10% level. All 2” We present the results normalized by the coefficients of real MlB variable such that /£.== 1.00. The parameters a and B are not identified since given any choice of the matrix §(rxr), (dé) and [3(§’)‘I also produces the same matrix I], and hence determine the same probability distribution for the variables. The data can only determine the space spanned by the columns in B, and the space spanned by a. For identification of long-run parameters, see Rasche and Hoffman (Chapter 3, 1996). I64 estimates have smaller standard deviations than unrestricted estimates. The constrained estimated are reported in the Panel B of Table 22. Turning tx> the error correction coefficients U1), we can see that equilibrium errors cause real MlB and the umm rate to adjust downward, real GNP and the own rate to adjust upward. We also notice that the weight of the equilibrium errors loading to the change of real balances is very small in unrestricted VAR(4) model (Panel A, Table 22). Ihl both models, the equilibrium error enters the umm equation with largest. weights Chi absolute ‘value), suggesting' that 'the cointegration relation is important to the adjustment of the unorganized money market rates. For the VAR(3) model, the income elasticity (= 1.56) is significantly different from zero and unity. The interest semi—elasticity F= --0.017) has ea negative sign as conjectured but becomes insignificant. The error correction coefficients suggest that the equilibrium errors cause real MlB to adjust downward, real GNP and the spread to adjust upward. 26 The restriction ix; imposed (N1 the long-run information but not on the short—run dynamics, (see Hoffman, Rasche, and Tieslau 1995). 165 Table 22 Normalised cointegrating vectors (fl) and error correction coefficients (a) Panel A Unrestricted VAR(4) with k = 7, x = (RMlB,y,i",umm) flm fly flib flumm b 1.00 —1.45 -0.35 0.05 (0.23) (0.32) (0.07) (0.07) Eq. ARMlB Ay ,Afl Aumm & -0.003 0.04 0.16 -0.29 Panel B Restricted VAR(4) with ,6, = -,BW (LR = 1.37)‘ flu: fly fli" flumm & 1.00 -1.61 -0.02 0.02 (0.14) (0.20) (0.01) (0.01) Eq. ARMlB Ay ,Afl Aumm A -0.03 0.04 0.07 —0.72 a Panel C VAR(3) with k = 5, x = (RMlB,y,umm-i") fl” fly flmmn-i‘ A 1.00 —1.56 0.017 fl (0.27) (0.23) (0.090) A -0.12 0.01 0.41 a Note: Figures ( ) are standard deviations. Also see notes to Table 20. LR is the log likelihood ratio test stastistic for A 5, = -flmm against H2 (Eq.3.20), which is asymptotically distributed as 1595(1) = 3.84. 166 Table 23 Critical values for trace and km“ p—r 80% 90% 95% 80% 90% 95% Model I Model 11 Trace Trace 1 1.66 2.69 3.76 8.65 10.49 12.25 2 11.07 13.33 15.41 20.19 22.76 25.32 3 23.64 26.79 29.68 35.56 39.06 42.44 4 40.15 43.95 47.21 54.80 59.14 62.99 Amax A’max 1.66 2.69 3.76 8.65 10.49 12.25 10.04 12.07 14.07 14.70 16.85 18.96 16.20 18.60 20.97 20.45 23.11 25.54 21.98 24.73 27.07 26.30 29.12 31.46 bWNP—J Note: Critical values are taken from Table 1.amui Table 2' in Osterwald-Lenum 1992. V} ESTIMATION AND TESTS OF LINEAR RESTRICTIONS ON THE LONG- RUN PARAMETERS OF DEMAND FOR REALIMIB IN TAIWAN 1 Estimation of the Long—Run Income and Interest Elasticities The long-run demand for money plays an important role in the quantitative analysis of the effects of monetary policy; buxfll of the empirical money demand literature has focused on the search for a stable short-run money demand function. In such cases, the efficient estimators can be used in subsequent stages of the analysis by imposing the estimated cointegrating vectors, for example in a VBCM (King, Plosser, Stock enui Watson 1991), or :hl a, single- 167 equation error correction framework (Hendry and Ericsson 1991). In this section, we compare estimates of the long-run parameters for the demand for real MlB using four asymptotic efficient estimators, OLS (Engle and Granger 1987, Stock 1987), the fully modified estimators of Phillips and Hansen (1990) (FM) and Johansen’s (1988b) VECM maximum likelihood estimator (JOH) and Stock and Watson (1993) DOLS. The last three estimators have an asymptotic distribution that is a random mixture of normals and produce Wald test statistics with asymptotic chi-squared distribution. In each estimation, again we consider both four- variable system x,= (RMlB,y,V,umm) and three-variable system >g== (RMlB,y,unmvib). Estimates cu? the cointegrating vectors are normalized such that am = -1.00 and are reported in Table 24. We use the cmmained point estimates and their standard errors to test the significance of each regressors. In the VAR(4) model, the estimates are very close across the estimators and the coefficients on each variable have the expected signs. The income elasticity is around 1.50 and is significantly different from zero and unity at either 5% or 10% (unrestricted JOH in VAR(4)) level for all estimators. The interest semi—elasticity (the own rate 6%) is significantly from zero only for the Johansen estimator, 168 A which is largest among the estimators. HWW is similar across estimators and significantly different from zero except in Johansen’s estimation. Under the constraint ,Q, = -,B,,,,,,,,, which cannot be rejected by the data (LR = 1.37, see Panel B, Table 22), the interest rate spread in Johansen's estimator becomes significant. In VAR(3), the income elasticity and interest semi— elasticity are almost identical across estimators. Surprisingly, Johansen estimates have the largest standard deviation among all the estimators. The interest variable is not significant in the Johansen estimation at either 5% or 10% level. Under the constraint 8, == -1.50, the interest semi-elasticity from JOH becomes more precisely estimated (with much smaller standard deviation) and turns out to be significant. Since the own rate is run: significant across the estimators except JOH, in Table 25, we also report the results obtained in the regressions only using the umm rate. We find that the estimates are similar to those using the spread (the right three columns of Table 24). In all cases, 0 is significantly different from unity at time 5% level; 1 E) is significantly different from zero at either 5% and ”NH” 10% level. From Table 24, although all four asymptotic efficient estimators generate qualitatively' and. statistically close 169 estimates, Johansen estimator generally produces larger standard, deviations among' all estimators considered. Surprisingly, the analysis based on a complete model (Johansen 1991), where the different variables are jointly modeled and a full information analysis is pursued, does not have efficiency gains in estimating the long—run parameters”. This is consistent with the simulation results in Stock and Watson (1993). Our study provides an empirical example that single equation methods (xvi also efficiently estimate long-run equilibria, as advocated in Phillips and Loretan (1991), Stock and Watson (1993). To conclude the estimation of the long-run demand for real MlB in Taiwan, we present the graphs for the actual real MlB (denoted RLMlB in figures) and the estimated real MlB generated by the estimates of Table 24 to see how well these regressions track the data. Figure 15 and 16 plot the comparison of the estimated values across estimators for the four-variable system (denoted OLS4, DOLS4, FM4, JOH4, REJOH4) and three—variable system (denoted OLSB, DOLS3, FM3, JOH3), respectively. For each estimator, we also compare the estimated real MlB obtained from the four- and three- variable system with the actual real MlB; they are presented in Figure 17 - 20. 27 I thank Professor" Wooldridge. for the comments on this empirical finding. 170 From Figure 15 - 20, we can see all the estimators except unrestricted JOH (JOH4) track the data well either we use two interest rates or the spread in the regression. We notice that the actual MlB/P is above the estimated value across estimation during 1986-91; this period coincides the boom of the stock exchange market in Taiwan. 171 Table 24 Estimated Cointegrating relations: RMlB,=-p.+9yy,+0,i,+e, OLS x = (RMlB,yyi",umm) x = (RMlB,y,umm-ih) £1 &, é,‘ émfl [Al av guano—I. —6.50 1.52 0.05 -0.021 -6.80 1.55 -0.023 (0.29) (0.02) (0.03) (0.004) (0.13) (0.01) (0.003) DOLS' —6.21 1.50 0.10 —0.025 -6.89 1.55 -0.017 (1.27) (0.09) (0.14) (0.016) (0.65) (0.04) (0.012) PM2 -6.42 1.53 0.06 -0.025 -6.81 1.55 —0.017 (0.89) (0.07) (0.09) (0.010) (0.48) (0.03) (0.010) JOH VAR(4) VAR(3) —5.05 1.45 0.35 -0.050 -6.92 1.56 -0.017 (0.32) (0.07) (0.075) (0.23) (0.092) Restricted VAR(4) with '6)" = - m” VAR(3) with ,6, = -1.50 -7.57 1.61 0.02 -0.02 -6.83 1.50 -0.016 (0.20) (0.01) (0.01) (0.28) (0.004) Note: 1 DOLS estimation regression: k k RMlB = p. + (ivy, + 9,i, + Zd,L-’Ay, + 2g,L-’Ai, + a, I=-k j=-k where i is a vector containing interest rates. We set the number of leads and lags k = 2 and use AR(2) error process to implement DOLS covariance matrix and estimate the standard errors. 2 The frequency zero spectral estimator required for FM are computed. using" prewhitened. quadratic spectral kernel and automatic bandwidth estimator(see Section II eumi 111 this Chapter). Figures in parenthesis are standard deviations. 172 Table 25 Estimated Cointegrating relations: RMIB, = u + Oyy, + 0 III!!!” um, +8, ) [1 av an"! OLS -6.96 1.56 -0.016 (0.12) (0.01) (0.003) DOLS -7.04 1.56 -0.015 (1.47) (0.04) (0.011) PM —6.96 1.56 —0.015 (0.44) (0.03) (0.009) JOH —7.05 1.57 -0.016 (0.26) (0.008) A8323 o_no_.m>.._:ou= Em :2 omen—=33 can 333‘ "2. 2:2". 3 vm _. e . . . . . M . _. . ._ o . . .8. . . we we .. IR ...-Ee».--.tm».r.m».-_.,_,$..-.$. ......(oéi . ,/ ‘3 I Y LC 1.1L .4 < I x ( (st . \/ \.>\\.\\ .\)\/\\ (\x \.\ . \Lw /\ .<\ \X ( \\. \ \( Amezumvdamezaaoov O \z \2\ ) x (A \ i- 1 H...\\| \ .fl\\//.\ /\ \)\\<\I~ \ \I\ (5 <, (Z «roam (I .\ 2 \ t \(0 so. i ,. , 3E - | /\ «m,_oo - - I «who - - I 95:”. 1| or 2. NF 2 E. 2 or 174 A5326 o_oa_..u>.oo.:._._.v Em :2 omen—:33 one 3304‘ "or 2:9”. 3.. . 3 15.-.. ..es. 1. .mm .. «mt--. a.» etflt-.-.m»...t, m . .... .r( 1 #0..» L 1.51mLFLuwww s. _. elf—.10.: - .J/ ., w 7 \ . 5. 7 . . 14 i \ \(/ \\\r 1 R; ,. 5 \ Is .... \\\d\ 1 /\.N\)..\ \ \)\. \ \\\ «(A - \\( \\ \ H.\ Ill dek «roe ( ..L x ( AEEEZBEES... 2E - I (5(4) 838 --I Kr“) \ 8.5 - - - m1 95¢ 11 Qm for N._._. C.NF 93. 92 v.3 «.9. 175 5:858 30 "dame: 835:8 use .52 ”t 2:2". 176 . No 1 S . .vm , _ . “rm. 1 .. uwm1 _ 1 _mm 1 _ 1mNem-_)i_F1m11oleLmWEFMF “m1-$9._1e1701$cm 1 _N_wr.1_r._¢l©_1_i _.—.®, - 7’ \. 7\\ .L I / \ \ 2\ .\,\ \\ \/;\\< 2 (< A 8:35 dams: .58 \x \1 (\ \ \. \ <1 \ «woo -- I A. < «90 - - - (x. a 953m .lI seesaw»... moon ”dimes. 355:8 see 332 "2 2:2“. s . _ .1. . s... ......slttm ...-.-m 21.1.12. or 11.--; 8 I v.9. W N._._. ( C.N.. ( QNF ..- 0.9 ..- v.3 New 177 oozes—58 .E ”dame: 835:8 new .52 no. 2:9“. 8,» . .81. r .8 w. . .8. .-....s, .8.. .-. 1-18.1. _ .. 1e.“ . .. 1.x. 1% . famine -.-.. 1 3 e s \)\ a \ \ 1 » \/\ \x. I \v\\\( /\ \ 19:31:19.2 .381 \ \ r \ «flxt I 1E - - I s \( ms: - - - \\ 9:2 I v.2. N: ode mNF 0.2. v.3. .022. 178 .3... 1.28538 :9. "Ems: 8658.. use .252 an 959“. . 1 ..s: 1 1 £1 13.111Wm. 1 .-ms11-1-(m»..1 111.11%. 11 $1-115 1 hm .- Axioms $10.. 8858116 1.2 11' 0d «.3 N: C.N— 99. 0.9. v.3. «.9. 179 2 Tests of Linear Restrictions on Cointegrating vectors (6) and the Adjustment Coefficients (a) Because we are not only interested in inference about the~ cointegrating' relations tun; also 1J1 their" adjustment coefficients, the Johansen’s likelihood ratio tests provide us tests for linear structural hypothesis CH1(X and 8. Note that the Wald statistics for linear restrictions on cointegrating vectors constructed from DOLS and FM also have asymptotic x2 distribution. The likelihood ratio test (M? the linear restrictions about [3 and a, H4 : ,B =IH¢ and a = Ay/ are constructed from solving both the unrestricted eigenvalue problem and restricted eigenvalue problem. (for detail see Johansen and Juselius 1990, Jehansen. 11991). Since tflma asymptotic distribution of the maximum likelihood estimator is mixed Gaussian, the hypotheSis about cointegrating relations is to use the x2 distribution. (1) Tests of linear restrictions on,fl First, we test the unitary income elasticity hypothesis for the VAR(4) model H1: flm = — fly 180 The likelihood ratio (LR) for H; against H2 is computed as LR = 0.85, which is compared x395<1> = 3.84 so the unit income elasticity hypothesis cannot be rejected an: the 5% level. The inability of rejection is also consistent with t test constructed from Johansen estimates, however it is inconsistent with t-ratios constructed by DOLS and PHFM. As pointed out in Hoffman, Rasche and Tieslau (1995), the difference in inference between the Johansen and the single equation estimation (FM here) follows from the ex ante and ex post normalization that distinguishes the two estimators. Next the hypothesis that the coefficients for the own rate of MlB and the umm rate are equal with opposite sign is tested. The likelihood ratio for Hg is computed as LR = 1.37. Thus we fail to reject Hi at the 5% level, which is consistent with the Wald test from FM (Table 12). Since we fail to reject both H; and Hi, we go on to test the joint hypothesis of H; : ,8," = — ,6, and 6,. = "13...”. against H2 181 The likelihood ratio is 7.00, which is compared x§_95(1) = 3.84. Interestingly, H; is rejected at the 5% level even though both flm = — fl, and (”*‘="flmm are rejected as shown above. Moving to VAR(3) model, we compute the likelihood ratio for Lg :,fly = -1.50 versus H2 as LR = 1.60. Therefore, we fail to reject the null at the 5% level. (2) Weak exogeneity tests We examine whether some variables in the system are weakly exogeneous for the long-run parameters a and B, i.e. for some i, a, = 0, where i is an index of variables in the system. If Ax” is weakly exogenous for a and 8 in the sense that the conditional distribution of Ax, given Ax" as well as the lagged values of x, contains the parameters a and 8, whereas all distribution of Ax,, given the lagged x, does not contain the parameters a and 8. Furthermore, the parameters in the conditional and marginal distribution are variation free, (Johansen and Juselius 1990, 1992, Johansen 1991a). Urbain (1992) demonstrates. that the .rejection. of weak exogeneity status of the various variables sufficiently invalidates inference conducted in single error correction 182 model (for' both long-run. and short-run parameters)fla In other words, the single equation ECM has parameters which are themselves a function of the parameters of the marginal process. Under such circumstance, one needs to conduct the analysis based on both marginal and conditional model, i.e. the full model. In VAR(4) model, since the hypothesis ,6, = -,3,,,,,,,, cannot be rejected by the data, we test hypothesis about a in the restricted model under A. = -flm,,, that is, HQ: 01. = I 0 and 6,, = -,Bumm versus Hi: ,8, = ":an For VAR(3), we test the hypothesis of H: ,6, -1.50 and a, = 0 against ,8}, = - 1.50. Table 26-27 reports the likelihood ratio (LR), which is asymptotically' distributed. as ea x2(1) distribution under the null hypothesis (for our case r'== 1). We can see the test statistic for each hypothesis that the cointegrating relations are not present in the equation determining each variable in the system is rejected at the 5% level for both VAR(4) and VAR(3) model. It indicates none of variables in the system can be treated as weakly exogenous in estimation of the long-run parameters a and E5