. ylh!‘ , w_ ,<.- c «1vv—n y-..- .. -hwu A4-.. uv-v-v .a u. .o- —— . 2...; A. m——- v . a -I ‘ A «‘r‘ ._. . .. 3. «as: a . ké'i‘ffi 3423:“:t} ,- . 5‘ u . g. g.._ ._ ' . - 3 21 .m ‘ fizliiii": t. w". ”u...- wm. A _..,.~—- ...- n 4» .9:- if ’1 A} ‘ag .4 S l L "F34 I yu‘ ~ \ .«4 d .«E. v .v.‘ ~.._‘ "'3 "‘3”? A*¢~ _ ,v . l. \ ”Egan "I“ ":9 1 Lu, . .rgz ; $ u,’ :‘i. ‘1': .«Le :.;. 4: . -‘ , . . -,., *‘...,_:'z':a. M 5' .'.'_ ”54* 3 2 . i a: fiflzfl 1.11; 3):]? ‘5 M; ’i’ ~ 1" .l 1‘.) LI :fiL‘m‘ 11 .‘x‘ .44 t" A”: {‘1‘ : 1m}: 7‘“. 39‘ I} V.-- - . rw- . —.—~v . \- Z. I :13: ‘_ 311% ' . - * _ ,J }7 v ‘. H . ‘ l A, "l, 7 . :‘Q‘JQbU‘ _. «9% .. v“? x‘. \ 33.1.},2‘ , j, . 4., .1. . ‘;-v:,; "‘27:?! vr'” :‘N— .' ._..-- , _ _..I- . A ‘“‘r_h I - ' hwltgzusgzig. . , ‘. ‘ . "*ifis';§":._ee,l .221. ‘H ~‘~‘-"“’%.‘ , K .53?“ .. 3.2: .p "—y u...- ‘w u v Ar”: W- m _-.,~ w ..... .0... - '1.» ,- I .- - if h . $ in L1: ’ I‘IIJ "I (h e- t A l'ffiJ'.‘ u) .- o ‘ 0 V. -n..-. ' . #1.- ..‘_. . . 5....- TfiL-‘LBIS 199‘) 1 ImmulIlil’lllllllllllllllflumull 3 1293 01812 7252 This is to certify that the dissertation entitled TWO ESSAYS ON REPEALINC GLASS-STEAGALL ACT: REGULATION DISTORTION AND BANKS' ENTRY IN SECURITY UNDERWRITING presented by Wei-ling Song has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. Finance degree in Major professor / Date 5707/9? MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 042771 LIBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 1]” WM.“ TWO ESSAYS ON REPEALING GLASS-STEAGALL ACT: REGULATION DISTORTION AND BANKS' ENTRY IN SECURITY UNDERWRITING By Wei-ling Song A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Finance 1999 TMsc ACIc secur unde exan- SSCU' D€icr bank regul recei IeQU SWum 9035 SepV havG prov iSCx ABSTRACT TWO ESSAYS ON REPEALING GLASS-STEAGALL ACT: REGULATION DISTORTION AND BANKS' ENTRY IN SECURITY UNDERWRITING By Wei-ling Song This dissertation investigates the economic impact of repealing Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 on financial industry. The Act prohibits commercial banks from security underwritings. In 1987, commercial banks are allowed to engage in underwriting and dealing certain securities on a limited basis. The first essay examines three questions regarding commercial banks’ involvement in the security underwriting business in the post-section 20 era: (i) how does the ten percent revenue limitation distort the underwriting activities of commercial banks?, (ii) how different commercial banks are from investment banks under the regulatory and market conditions?, and (iii) which types of issuing firms do receive benefits from the bank-entry? We find evidence consistent with the regulatory distortion explanation that commercial banks are actively engaging in small issue market. Compared to investment banks, commercial banks do not possess better ability in underwriting for small issuers. In fact, they are better in serving large clients but they can not handle large issue size. Commercial banks have better informational advantage. The association with commercial banks provides value to issuing firms. However, the evidence supports that the market is concerned for conflicts of interest and informational monopoly power of commercial banks. Due to the pros and cons of commercial banks, only issuers with middle credit ratings receive significant benefits from bank entry. Whereas, small issuers with high credit ratings and large issuers with low credit ratings are suffered from the banks' expansion at the later entry stage. In the second essay, we examine empirically the economic rationales of coalitions of underwriters and the role of commercial banks as co-managers when they expand into the security underwriting business. We find evidence that commercial banks strategically select their mode of entry, either by leading the syndicates or by participating in syndicates led by an investment bank (the hybrid form), depending on their underwriting strength in different markets. By cooperating with a reputable investment bank, commercial banks can effectively reduce their conflicts of interest problem while preserving their informational advantages. The creation of a better organizational form in conducting security underwriting provides economic incentives for investment banks to accommodate the entry of commercial banks. The distinct functions offered by commercial banks facilitate their penetration into the security underwriting industry. In most cases, the hybrid structure is superior to both the commercial bank lead syndicate and to the pure investment bank arrangement. This paper highlights shortcomings of previous work in this area that focus only on issues that are commercial bank lead. By neglecting other organizational forms, such as hybrid syndicates, previous research understates the benefits that commercial banks bring into the security underwriting business. Copyright by Wei-ling Song 1999 To my parents, daughter and son. com Dr. C' espec comm COHUHI for offe Wlsdon ClCl‘lellt deeply Provide | A SPEC: Care Of famlly f gramme and Sat ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to express my appreciation to the members of my dissertation committee - Dr. Anil Shivdasani, Dr. Assem Safieddine, Dr. Naveen Khanna, and Dr. Charles Hadlock, for their insightful guidance and encouragement. I would especially like to thank Dr. Anil Shivdasani for all his help, patience, and commitment of time. I thank Dr. Richard Simonds for providing me with the opportunity to continue my doctoral studies. I also thank Dr. Kirt Butler and Dr. Geoffrey Booth for offering me a position as an instructor. I also appreciate the knowledge and wisdom passed on to me by all the faculty members in the Finance Department. I thank Dr. Miranda Lam Detzler, Aydin Yuksel, Ramana Sonti, Mike Cichello for helping me in one way or another throughout the finance program. I deeply appreciate my Taiwanese friends at Michigan State University who have provided constant encouragement throughout my stay in Michigan. I would like to thank all my family for their support, especially my parents. A special thank to my sister, Wei-ching, who gives me peace of mind by taking care of my parents and my daughter. I would also like to thank Mrs. Tai and her family for providing such a loving environment for my son. Finally, my deepest gratitude goes to my daughter, Yihua, and my son, Jinha, for their understanding and sacrifices necessary for my completion of the doctoral program. vi LIST ES F lni TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ......................................................................... ix ESSAY 1. BANK-ENTRY BENEFITS AND REGULATION DISTORTION IN THE CORPORATE SECRURITY UNDERWRITING BUSINESS 1.1 Introduction ........................................................................... 1 1.2 Testable Hypotheses, Empirical Proxies and Prediction of Underwriter choice ................................................................. 10 1.2.1 The Information Advantage Hypothesis ............................. 11 1.2.2 The Conflicts of Interest Hypothesis .................................. 12 1.2.3 The Bank Relationship Hypothesis ................................... 14 1.2.4 The Bank Monopoly Power Hypothesis ............................. 15 1.3 The Switching Regression Model: Motivation and Description ......... 16 1.3.1 Model Specification ....................................................... 16 1.3.2 Estimation and Interpretation of Regression Estimates ......... 19 1.4 Data and Descriptive Statistics ................................................. 24 1.5 Regulatory Distortion and Comparative Advantages of Underwriters ......................................................................... 29 1.5.1 Regulatory Distortion of Commercial Bank Underwritings ....... 31 1.5.2 Advantages of Commercial Banks as Underwriters ............... 38 1.5.3 Disadvantages of Commercial Banks as Underwriters .......... 40 1.5.4 The Performance Comparison between Commercial Banks and Investment Banks ................................................... 42 1.6 Conclusions ......................................................................... 45 APPENDIX 1 TABLES OF ESSAY1 ................................................. 47 ESSAY L COMPETITION AliD COAEION AMONG UNIERWRITERS: 2.1 2.2 2.3 THE ENTRY STRATEGY OF COMMERCIAL BANKS IN THE POST-SECTION 29 ERA Introduction .......................................................................... 63 The Literature on Bank Entry Strategies and Underwriting Coalitions ............................................................................. 72 Data and Summary Statistics ................................................... 79 vii 24 25 26 APPE APPE APPE MBLM 2.4 The Entry Strategies of Commercial Banks ................................. 83 2.5 The Characteristics of Hybrid Syndicates .................................... 88 2.5.1 The Determinants of Syndicate Selections ......................... 89 2.5.2 The Underwriting Abilities of Syndicates ............................ 91 2.5.3 The Performance of Syndicates ....................................... 95 2.6 Conclusion ........................................................................... 99 APPENDIX 2 TABLES OF ESSAY 2 ............................................... 101 APPENDIX A. DATA DEFINITIONS ................................................. 119 APPENDIX B. TABLES ................................................................. 123 BIBLIOGRAPHY ........................................................................... 132 viii Tabl Tabl Table Table Table Table ‘ Table 1 Table 1 Table 1 Table 2 Table 2 Table 2 Table 1.1 Table 1 .2 Table 1.3 Table 1.4 Table 1.5 Table 1.6 Table 1.7 Table 1.8 Table 1.9 Table 2.1 Table 2.2 Table 2.3 LIST OF TABLES Summary of theoretical predictions regarding choice of commercial bank (vs. investment bank) ............................ 48 Descriptive statistics of bond issue and firm characteristics by year and by underwriter-type ...................................... 50 Descriptive statistics of bond issue by issue size market and by underwriter-type ................................................ 52 Issuer credit ratings distribution and basis point spreads by underwriter-type ...................................................... 53 Estimates of the determinants of underwriter selections and basis point spreads on bonds underwritten by the commercial banks or by investment banks ........................ 54 Small issue market: Estimates of the determinants of underwriter selections and basis point spreads on bonds underwritten by the commercial banks or by investment banks ......................................................... 56 Large issue market: Estimates of the determinants of underwriter selections and basis point spreads on bonds underwritten by the commercial banks or by investment banks ......................................................... 58 Gross benefit for firm using the service of chosen undenlvriter rather than that of unchosen underwriter. ......................... 60 Gross benefit for firm using the service of chosen undenNriter rather than that of unchosen underwriter for small issue market and large issue market by subperiods. ................... 61 The frequency and percentage of bond issues by year and by underwriter type. ................................................ 102 Descriptive statistics of bond issue and firm characteristics by year and by underwriter type ....................................... 104 Issuer credit ratings distribution and basis point spreads by undenlvriter type ....................................................... 106 Tabb Tabb Tabb Tabb Tame. Appenq Append Append: Appendi Appendj; ’Table 2.4 Table 2.5 Table 2.6 Table 2.7 Table 2.8 LIST OF TABLES (CONT'D) The percentage of bond issues by underwriter-type in the large issue and small issue markets ......................... 108 Estimates of the determinants of syndicate selections .......... 110 Estimates of basis point spreads on bonds underwritten by CB-Lead and Hybrid syndicates. ................................. 112 Estimates of basis point spreads on bonds underwritten by PurelB syndicate ...................................................... 114 Gross benefit for issuing firms by credit ratings using the service of chosen syndicate rather than that of unchosen syndicate ....................................................... 116 Appendix B1 Estimates of basis point spreads on bonds underwritten by the commercial banks or by investment banks with alternative model specifications ................................. 124 Appendix 82 Small issue market: Estimates of basis point spreads on bonds undenivritten by the commercial banks or by investment banks with alternative model specifications ......... 126 Appendix B3 Gross benefit for firm using the service of chosen underwriter rather than that of unchosen underwriter: Estimated from alternative model specification ................... 128 Appendix B4 Estimates of additional basis point spreads regressions on bonds underwritten by hybrid syndicate with endogenous selection adjustment term ............................. 129 Appendix BS Additional estimation of gross benefit for issuing firms by credit ratings using the service of chosen syndicate rather than that of unchosen syndicate .............................. 131 £55 11 R financi to rape prohibl" Ofthis; inveSUr Th banks: Subsidi. ESSAY 1. BANK-ENTRY BENEFITS AND REGULATION DISTORTION IN THE CORPORATE SECRURITY UNDERWRITING BUSINESS 1.1 Introduction Recently, Congress and regulators have undertaken measures to reform the financial services industry. These efforts include, among other things, a proposal to repeal the Glass-Steagall Act‘. The Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 effectively prohibited commercial banks from underwriting corporate securities. As a result of this act, all US. corporate security issues could be underwritten only by investment banks for nearly six decades. The relaxation of the Glass-Steagall Act since 1989 has allowed commercial banks to engage in these investment banking activities through their Section 20 subsidiaries under firewall restrictions and a 10 percent revenue limitationz. The ‘ See, for instance, the bill (HR 1062) proposed by Representative Leach, Chairman of the House Banking Committee, on February 27, 1995. In general, HR. 1062, the Financial Services Competitiveness Act of 1995, is intended to permit affiliations between full-service depository institutions and full-service securities companies (Congressional Reports, 1995—1996, House Reports 104-127). See JP Morgan & Co. Inc., The Chase Manhattan Corp., Bankers Trust New York Corp., Citicorp, and Security Pacific Corp., 75 Federal Reserve Bulletin 192 (1989) (hereafter, 1989 Order) for a discussion of Section-20 subsidiary, firewall and revenue limitation. Basically, Section 20 of the Glass-Steagall Act states that a member bank of the Federal Reserve System may not be affiliated with a company that is “engaged principally" in underwriting and dealing in securities. The Board has established a revenue test to determine whether a company is “engaged principally” in underwriting and dealing for purposes of section 20. The revenue test provides that a section 20 subsidiary may not derive more than 10 percent of its total revenue from underwriting and dealing in bank-ineligible securities. Bank-ineligible securities refer to the ones commercial banks are allowed to deal and underwrite after the change of regulation. Firewalls are a set of restrictions that limit the financial and information flows between the securities and commercial bank subsidiaries in an effort to insulate potential conflicts of interest that commercial banks may pass off bad loans to the market and use the proceeds to pay off bank debt. 10 percent revenue limitation effectively eliminates the possibility that commercial banks may enter the securities business by acquiring an existing investment bank. Following the increase of the revenue limitation to 25 percent at the end of 1996‘, there were some mergers between commercial banks and investment banks, such as Bankers Trust's merger with Alex, Brown, Inc. and Citicorp's merger with Travelers. In contrast to investment banks who do not have any revenue constraint, commercial banks may be limited by this revenue restriction in the amount of issues they can underwrite. This restriction might also cause them to deviate from the clientele they can serve the best. Whether the revenue limitation has material effects on the behavior of commercial banks has yet to be investigated. Additionally, it is unclear if issuing firms are suffering from possible regulation distortion. Besides the observed distortion of bank entry modes, we analyze in this paper the impact of revenue restriction on the underwriting ability of commercial banks and their client firms. Gande et al (1997) studied commercial bank underwriting activities since 1989, and found that the issue size of commercial bank clients decreased during the period 1993-95. The authors argue that commercial banks are better in bringing smaller firms into the public debt market. However, they do not examine the firm size explicitly in the their study. Although it is true that the issues of small 3 See Federal Reserve System Docket No. R-0841, “Revenue Limit on Bank-Ineligible Activities of Subsidiaries of Bank Holding Companies Engaged in Underwriting and Dealing in Securities." firms tend to be smaller“, the matching of issuer and underwriter based on these two dimensions of size depends on the different abilities of underwriters. The firm size dimension is associated with the certification ability of undenrvriter, whereas issue size is related to the distribution ability of unden/vriter. These two abilities may not have a perfect correlation with each other, like the positive relationship between issue size and firm size. In addition, the 10 percent revenue limitation imposed only on commercial banks may hinder their ability in handling large issue size, even though they may be better in serving large firms. Using a sample of 1327 corporate bond issues from 1991 to 1996, we formally examine the abilities of commercial banks and investment banks in assisting issuers with different issue sizes and firm sizes. We test the hypothesis that commercial banks actively engage in the small issue market because of regulatory distortions rather than because of commercial banks' superior ability in underwriting for small firms. Since commercial banks are new entrants in the security underwriting business, one might argue that they are at a disadvantage with respect to distribution capabilities, because it takes time to establish distribution networks. If this is true, we should observe commercial banks improve their distributional ability over time. So, we examine the performance of commercial banks in serving their clients across different time periods. We also segment the total underwriting market by the median issue size to further investigate the differences of commercial bank underwriting between large and small issue ‘ The correlation coefficient between these firm size and issue size is 0.34. mark pron: E banks dbad\ assoc rnonn hflonn; provide Howev banksi locapu Rwan( [Ani thhis 1933.I( markets. The regulatory distortion from the revenue constraint should be more pronounced in the large issue market than the small issue market. Besides regulatory differences between commercial banks and investment banks, there have been extensive debates regarding the advantages and disadvantages of banks as lenders and underwriters. The advantages of bank association have been the subject of much theoretical and empirical works. The monitoring activity of a bank gives commercial banks a role as credible information certifiers (Fama, 1985, Diamond, 1991). Bank relationships may also provide insurance against credit rationing when times are tough (Holland, 1994). However, the informational role of commercial banks comes with a cost, since banks can acquire monopoly power over clients' information, allowing the banks to capture a greater share of firm profits. Issues of this sort are discussed in Rajan (1992), Sharpe (1990) and Greenbaum et al (1989). Another disadvantage of commercial banks is a potential conflict of interest, which is the main concern prompting the passage of the Glass-Steagall Act in 1933. Kanatas and Qi (1998) study the cost of conflicts of interest imposed on commercial bank clients when the investors suspect that there is a potential for the commercial banks to misrepresent the quality of their customers and to pass off bad loans to the market, enabling the firm to use the proceeds to repay bank debt. Despite this cost, firms may choose to use the services of commercial 5 See James (1987) and Billett et al (1995) for empirical evidence on the value of bank association. DBDK unde differs banks wesh econo speda These monop VVI dlfieren eSIlmat basedc banks if there are sufficiently large scope economies in combined lending and underwritings. The existing empirical literature7 does not provide convincing evidence that different types of underwriters have comparative advantages. lf commercial banks as a group possess different abilities than those of investment banks, then we should observe a corresponding specialization in different segments of the economy. By using appropriate proxy variables, we further separate the test of specialization and comparative advantages of underwriters into finer hypotheses. These hypotheses include informational and relationship advantages, information monopoly power, and conflicts of interest of commercial banks. We test if there is a systematic selection of underwriters. We compare the differences between commercial banks and investment banks explicitly by estimating their bond pricing (net yield) equations and discuss these differences based on the above finer hypotheses. The regression coefficient differential on each firm or issue characteristic reveals how these two underwriters are different from each other on this particular dimension of issuers. Given that there is a systematic selection, this potential selection bias needs to be controlled for when the bond pricing equations are estimated. 6 For more detailed discussions of the arguments for and against the repeal of Glass- Steagall Act, see 1989 Order and Citicorp, JP. Morgan & Co., and Bankers Trust New York Corp., 73 Federal Reserve Bulletin 473 (1987). 7 See Ang and Richardson (1994), Puri (1994), Puri (1996), Hamao and Hoshi (1997), Gande et al (1997), and Kroszner and Rajan (1997) for more discussions of empirical results. Most of these studies support the view that there is a net certification effect of commercial banks. Only the study by Kroszner and Rajan (1997) showed there were concerns for conflicts of interest of commercial banks in the market. regma chmcl and o bawe bond r underv bond p underv clients theiss yield. l previo Unden F Under That d This leads to a natural application of the empirical model of switching regressions with endogenous switching". The model consists of an undenNriter choice equation, and two bond yield equations, one for commercial bank clients and one for investment bank clients. Thus, we allow complete interactions between issuer characteristics and underwriter identity when we estimate the bond pricing equations to contrast the differences between these two types of undenNriters. In addition to disentangling the forces underlying the formation of bond prices, this model also allows us to compare the performance of undenivriters by quantifying the benefits that different undenNriters create for their clients. The benefit is defined as the expected mean net yield of the issuer had the issue been underwritten by the unselected undenivriter, less the actual net yield. Instead of comparing the net yields of different regimes of issuers as in previous studies, we are able to compare a firm’s net yield given the selected underwriter, to the net yield had the client chosen the unselected undenNriter. Firms with different characteristics may have a variety of different needs for undenlvriting services. These needs should be matched with the varied abilities that different underwriters possess. Thus, the entry of commercial banks could be beneficial to certain types of firms. On the other hand, the existence of switching costs (Nanda and Warther, 1998) may prevent commercial bank clients from using services of investment banks. Therefore, we investigate the economic role that commercial banks play in the security underwriting business and analyze what types of firms are better off or worse off due to the bank entry. 8 See Maddala (1983) for an explanation of this model. 4 .,-rm‘d arm‘- Tobm’S q I sma seg The bank Funhi the fir bank( increa banks the sar choose inability clients. perform later ent T Choice 0 enufifica trade leSs It appears from our results that commercial banks actively participate in the small issue market because of regulatory constraints, rather than being in this segment voluntarily due to any comparative advantage in assisting small issuers. The results of the overall sample show that the underwriting ability of commercial banks is better than that of investment banks along the firm size dimension. Furthermore, in the large-issue market, the differences between underwriters in the firm size dimension are more pronounced. However, these large commercial bank clients incur huge price discounts when the size of their bond issues increases; this is not true for investment bank clients. The ability of investment banks to serve different size of customers, regardless of firm size or issue size, is the same in both small and large issue markets. If commercial banks could choose, they would have underwritten a greater number of larger clients, but their inability to handle large issue sizes prohibits them from underwriting for large clients. This regulatory distortion hypothesis is further supported by the performance of commercial banks, which worsen in the large issue market at the later entry stage. This paper also establishes empirically that the forces underlying the choice of undenrvriter for security issuance suggested by previous theoretical and empirical work do exist. The informational advantage that commercial banks have facilitates their underwriting firms that are less risky (lower leverage), that trade less frequently, are rated lower and that have higher Tobin’s q. Since Tobin’s q may be a proxy for investment opportunities, the commercial bank association with high Tobin’s q clients also supports the notion that a commercial bank relati that t mfled abHfiy (finanr increa: investr comme resuhs informa by the s are Sll’or i"formati bank relationship is beneficial to firms with higher financing needs. The positive relation between lower rated issuers and commercial banks supports the views that bank monitoring and certification are more valuable to firms in this segment. Besides their observed specialization in underwriting for less risky, lower rated firms with higher informational problems, commercial banks have a better ability than investment banks in undenivriting along the dimensions of leverage (financial risk) and Tobin's q. When the leverage and Tobin's q of client firms increase, commercial bank underwritten bonds have lower net yields than investment bank underwritten bonds. Further, we present evidence to show that commercial banks can cherry pick9 from among available client firms. These results are consistent with the hypothesis that commercial banks have informational and relationship-based advantages. When we separate the sample by the size of issue, the informational advantage and bank relationship effects are stronger in the small issue market. Not surprisingly, in the large issue market, the benefits of bank association decrease because these issuers have less of an informational problem and better access to the capital markets. We find that the concerns for conflicts of interest rise when firms having high interest expense relative to operating income are associated with commercial banks, especially when the purpose of issue is to repay bank debt. We do not find the intent to refinance bank debt by itself a proxy for potential conflicts of interest. In fact, when the use of proceeds is for refinancing bank debt and the 9 Cherry picking refers to the ability of commercial banks to select "higher quality" firms based on their private information about clients. See Section 1.3 for a detailed explanation of how the endogenous selection of firms ties into the cherry picking ability than: banks mame range with ve entry ii that the andinh rated 5, “IOCked. T hl’pothe dhCusse DIESents regulatm im'leSImE UIIGErwrm level of interest expense is low, there is no price discount of the bond regardless of underwriter. We also document that the market is concerned about the informational monopoly problem with commercial banks, especially for firms with high stock return volatility, high profitability and higher past sales growth. Although it appears that the benefits created by investment banks are larger than those created by commercial banks, this does not mean that investment banks are better underwriters than commercial banks across all segments of the market. Consistent with Diamond (1991), firms with credit ratings in a middle range receive the most benefits from commercial bank relations. However, firms with very high and very low credit ratings do not benefit from commercial bank entry in general. The results are also consistent with the theory in Rajan (1992) in that there is a trade-off in developing relationship-specific capital between firms and intermediaries. Negative benefits created by commercial banks for the best rated small issuers implies that these smaller, better firms are the clients being “locked-in”. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 1.2, the testable hypotheses, empirical proxies and prediction of undewvriter choice are discussed. Section 1.3 motivates and describes our empirical model. Section 1.4 presents the data and descriptive statistics. Section 1.5 reports the effects of regulatory distortion and the comparative advantages of commercial banks and investment banks. Section 1.6 concludes. underwriters. cl" '- ‘Jt'iit-K‘L IO‘ Th studie 1994: subsid and R; befler vauhi find ev Undem inform; SUDDOr COUCen 1.2 Testable Hypotheses, Empirical Proxies and Prediction of Underwriter Choice The role of commercial banks as both lenders and underwriters has been studied using data both prior to the Glass-Steagall Act (Ang and Richardson, 1994; Puri, 1994; Puri, 1996; Kroszner and Rajan, 1997) and the post-section-20 subsidiary era (Gande et al, 1997). The results are mixed. Except for Kroszner and Rajan (1997), all the studies support the view that commercial banks are better certifiers of public debt issues because of informational advantages acquired from lending to issuing firms. Taken as a whole, these studies do not find evidence of conflicts of interest that lead commercial banks to systematically underwrite bad loans. Contrary to these findings, by controlling for the informational advantages of banks, Kroszner and Rajan (1997) report results that support the argument that when lending and underwriting are closely combined, concerns for conflicts of interest do exist. Nonetheless, these studies do not address the issue of how firms select between different underwriters and do not control for the endogenous selection problem when the net yield equations are estimated. The comparative advantages of underwriters have never been investigated using characteristics of issuing firms. By using appropriate proxy variables, we are able to disentangle different forces that have material effects on bond pricing. In the following subsections, we discuss the hypotheses related to the comparative advantages of underwriters; the firm and issue characteristics can 10 fl... be us Theo sumn advar banks 1.2.1 Tt banks. Thbinl mmes. with mg banks a with Iarg DrodUCe plobabili grecliter g In or ones With firm with c c:Ommerclg be used to test these hypotheses along with the prediction of underwriter choice. Theoretical predictions of undenNriter choice from each hypothesis are summarized in Table 1.1. These hypotheses include information and relationship advantage, conflicts of interest, and information monopoly power of commercial banks. 1.2.1 The Information Advantage Hypothesis Through periodic monitoring and ongoing deposit histories, commercial banks can acquire private information about their clients in a cost-effective way. This information advantage gives banks a unique role in serving issuers with more serious information problems (Fama, 1985; James, 1987). Therefore, firms with higher information asymmetry receive greater benefits by using commercial banks as their underwriters. The information problem is more severe for firms with larger growth opportunities. Commercial banks as low cost information producers are more beneficial for smaller firms than larger ones. Therefore the probability of choosing a commercial bank is higher if the firm is smaller, has greater growth opportunities, and has a lower credit rating. ln Diamond (1991), bank monitoring provides value to firms, especially to the ones with credit ratings in the middle range. Therefore, we should observe that firm with credit ratings in the middle range tend to be associated more with commercial banks than with investment banks. Both Titman and Trueman (1986) and Chemmanur and F ulghieri (1994) model the effects of undewvriters with 11 "s ’l "I“. l 5 m1- inforr therr tends inforn' procee inform Mgher ween Opporti mamet finnsfiz depend 12;? information advantages. They conclude that the higher the quality of underwriter, the more effective it is in reducing the impact of information asymmetry and it tends to reject a firm with a risky project. Consequently, underwriters with better information undenivrite less risky client firms and obtain a higher price (net proceeds) for the underwritten security. Given that commercial banks possess an information advantage, the probability of choosing one as an underwriter is higher if the firm is less risky. The empirical proxies for information asymmetry are exchange listing“), volatility of equity return, equity trading volume, growth opportunity (measured by Tobin’s q, sales growth), and firm size (defined as the market value of equity). The proxy related to information cost effectiveness is the firm size. The variables for credit ratings are defined in two different ways depending on the purpose of use". 1.2.2 The Conflicts of Interest Hypothesis The issue of conflicts of interest of commercial banks has been discussed in both empirical and regulatory literatures‘z. Due to the perception of greater conflicts of interest, it should be more difficult for commercial banks to convince the public of the value of these securities than for investment banks. As ‘° Exchange listing is dropped in the empirical analysis because only five percent of sample is not listed on an exchange. 1‘ See Appendix A for more information. ‘2 For detailed discussion of conflicts of interest and the concerns of commercial banks as both lenders and underwriters, see “JP. Morgan 8 Co. Inc., the Chase Manhattan Corp., Bankers Trust New York Corp., Citicorp, and Security Pacific Corp.,” 75 Federal Reserve Bulletin 192 (1989), Puri (1996), and Kroszner and Rajan (1997). 12 suggested by Kroszner and Rajan (1997), organizations with greater conflicts of interest should specialize more in issues with less information problems and less risk. Thus, firms possessing characteristics that might be viewed as causing conflicts of interest are less likely to choose commercial banks than investment banks as undenNriters in order to avoid the price discount. The perceived conflict of interest should be higher for firms with higher risk and information asymmetry problems, with the most serious scenario being when the firm is also refinancing bank debt (Gande et al, 1997; Kroszner and Rajan, 1997). Therefore, the probability of choosing a commercial bank as an underwriter is smaller for firms with higher risk and information asymmetry problems and/or when the firm is refinancing bank debt. Given that the market is also using this information as proxies for potential conflicts of interest, the bond price of commercial bank clients should be lower than that of investment bank clients. The proxies used for risk are volatility of stock return, leverage, and interest expense relative to operating income; the predicted signs of probit estimates are negative”. ‘3 Although the predictions of underwriter selection are the same under both informational advantage and conflicts of interest hypotheses, the regression coefficients of net yield (BPS) regressions should be different. For instance, under the information advantage hypothesis, the beta coefficients of risk variables from commercial bank BPS regression should be smaller than that of investment bank BPS regression, because commercial banks can certify the information better than investment bank can. The commercial banks may reject the firm after the evaluation, so the association of commercial bank with riskier firm is lower, in Diamond (1991), monitoring of new, low quality borrowers can only be used as a screening device, many new borrowers will be turned down for credit because monitoring does not provide incentive for c00perative actions. This is an example that these three estimates in our empirical model does not agree with each other, because the selection is not determined by the bond yield differential. Whereas, under conflicts of interest hypothesis, the selection of underwriters shows the same'pattern, the reverse is true for the estimates of bond pricing equations, since investors will require a price discount when the perceived conflicts of interest is more serious. 13 11 1.2.. and anno that li again hetero loans, to be ; demar select more | T' andth Dione again: fUtU re 1.2.3 The Bank Relationship Hypothesis The value of bank relationships is documented in papers by James (1987) and Billett et al ( 1995). They find that the market response to bank loan announcements is positive. Holland (1994) points out in his case study research that lines of credit and borrowing limits on unsecured loans provide insurance against possible future credit rationing. But the value of the bank relationship is heterogeneous across firms. A cash rich and profitable firm relies less on bank loans, whereas unprofitable firms and firms experiencing high growth would like to be associated with banks because they may anticipate higher bank loan demand in the near future. This analysis thus leads to a lower probability of selecting commercial banks as underwriters by firms with more cash, that are more profitable and that anticipate slower growth. The empirical proxy used for cash in this study is cash and cash equivalents, and the proxy for profitability is operating income before depreciation. Growth is proxied by 5-year sales growth and Tobin’s q. Besides the insurance value against credit rationing, bank relationships could also provide better control of future agency and information asymmetry problems of firms. 14 Inl- . A flexib outsic power future circurr beher underv have hl higher I are the profitab 1.2.4 The Bank Monopoly Power Hypothesis Although banks provide the benefits of information certification and financial flexibility, the benefits come with costs. Since firms cannot communicate with outsiders about future prospects credibly, the bank has temporary monopoly power over a fin'n’s private information, allowing the bank to appropriate firms' future profits (Rajan, 1992; Sharpe, 1990; Greenbaum et al, 1989). In order to circumvent bank power, a firm with a greater information asymmetry problem“, better prospects”, and more free cash or higher profitability is less likely to be underwritten by a commercial bank. However, commercial bank clients tend to have higher cash reserve if the monopoly power of banks requires them to keep higher compensating balances. The empirical proxies for the information problem are the same as those in the information advantage hypothesis. The proxy for profitability is operating income before depreciation. 1‘ See infonnaticn advantage hypothesis for these proxies, the predicted signs under information monopoly hypothesis are opposite to that under information advantage hypothesis. ‘ The proxies are Tobin’s q and sales growth, under information monopoly hypothesis, the predicted signs of probit estimates should be negative. 15 1.3 1.3.1 It abilitie that 0: bond] select, unden selecti selecti Consid underv A Valid and the unseiec applica‘ eXplaim which sl reQTeSS,‘ advanta! 1.3 The Switching Regression Model: Motivation and Description 1 .3.1 Model Specification If commercial banks and investment banks have different underwriting abilities, then, all else being equal, bond-issuing firms will select the underwriter that can obtain the higher bond price. Therefore, the observed distribution of bond prices underwritten by each type of underwriter is conditional on this selection. The bond prices that could have been obtained by the unselected underwriter are not observable. Thus, there is a need to control for this self- selection when the bond pricing (or net yield) equation is estimated. Due to this selection, commercial bank and investment bank underwritten issues may be considered as representing two distinct regimes. The bond prices of issues underwritten by different types of underwriters are no longer directly comparable. A valid comparison would be the difference between the observed bond price and the expected bond price, had the same firm been underwritten by the unselected underwriter. The underlying selection mechanism leads to an application of switching regression with endogenous switching. This model, explained in detail in Maddala (1983), consists of a probit model estimation, which shows the determinants of underwriter selection and two net yield regressions for each type of underwriter, which contrast the comparative advantages of different underwriters. Formally, our empirical model is as follows: 16 where yield 0 banks. VECIOTS equafic 1, isao‘ tsunde, The Clli The error COIIan‘ancf y.,- = X13. + u“ (1) (for CB underwritten issues) y2, = X , ,82 + til, (2) (for IE underwritten issues) 1,’ = —(Z,7 — 5,) = —[X, (M) - (filing) (underwriter choice equation) where CB stands for commercial banks, lB for investment banks, y, is the net yield of bond for firm i, subscript 1 refers to issues undenNritten by commercial banks, subscript 2 refers to those underwritten by investment banks, X ,, Z, are vectors of exogenous firm characteristics. The standard deviation 0,,“ in ”It equation (3) is the standard deviation of u” — uh. Ii=1 iff li>0 (4) (yli O In this case the conditional mean net yields of both CB and IB underwritten issues are less than their unconditional means E(y,,.) and E(y2, ), respectively. Thus, those who choose commercial banks are better off than average firms if all firms are underwritten by the commercial banks, and those who choose investment banks are better off than average firms if all firms are undenlvritten by investment banks. Here, both commercial banks and investment banks specialize in certain segments of the market that cannot be 18 explail becau inform. Case 2 underv condnh the unc are bet beherc who Chl underw banks c Case 3; Case 4: issues a 7.3.2 E EQU; DamCUIa' dimensio explained by the publicly known firm characteristics. They coexist in the market because they possess distinct technologies in resolving the problem of private information of issuers. This is the best scenario for the economy. Case 2: a"; < O, 035 < 0 Here, the conditional mean net yield of commercial bank underwritten issues is less than the unconditional mean E(y,,), and the conditional mean net yield of investment bank undenlvritten issues is greater than the unconditional mean E(y2, ). Therefore, those who chose commercial banks are better off than average firm underwritten by both underwriters, but they are better off underwritten by commercial banks than by investment banks. Those who choose investment banks are below average firms, but they are better off underwritten by investment banks than by commercial banks, i.e. commercial banks can cherry pick the firms when they provide the undenivriting services. Case 3: 0'” > O, 0,: > O This is simply the reverse of Case 2. Case 4: 0'“. > O, 0'25 < 0 Given the setup of the model, this is impossible, because this implies that firms choose underwriters who underwrite the bond issues at higher yields, or lower bond prices. 1.3.2 Estimation and Interpretation of Regression Estimates Equation (3) is parallel to a probit estimation equation. If ,6, < ,62 for a particular variable, then a commercial bank has a comparative advantage on this dimension of the firm over an investment bank, so the probit estimate will be 19 positiv coeffic ofund: advan: exoger selectic explain as a prc measur informer Chi ofunder QGI this r be Client Of Ullden BeSideS’ for C93. hr Th InStanCe’ firms! the \ 6 7? The Droc We wm j; positive (—(,BI — fig) > 0) for that characteristic. Comparison of these beta coefficient differentials and the signs of probit estimates can identify the abilities of undenNriters and the determinants of underwriter selection. The comparative advantages of different underwriters can be then established through these exogenous variables. The adjustment terms used to control the endogenous selection can be used to examine the underlying selection that cannot be explained by those exogenous variables. Therefore, these terms can be viewed as a proxy of private information or overall ability of underwriters that cannot be measured by the exogenous variables, which are the publicly available information. Of course, the model has its limitations; if the forces that influence the choice of underwriters cannot be explained by the price effect differential, we may not get this relationship among these three estimates. An example of this force would be client switching costs where, due to temporary informational monopoly power of underwriter, the client may not be able to switch to preferred undenivriters. Besides, the ultimate decision of undenivriter choice is the net result of these forces, not just one of them. We follow the two-stage estimation procedure described in Maddala (1983)16 to estimate the parameters ,6,,,62, 0,5 and 02.- The framework of two net yield regressions is essential to our study". For instance, if commercial banks possess better ability in underwriting for large firms, the beta coefficient of firm size from the net yield regression will be smaller '° The procedure is discussed in Chapter 8 of Maddala (1983), pp.: 224-8. ‘7 We will label these net yield regressions as BPS regression for commercial bank (CB) 20 for co: increa more 1 banks model transla‘ cmnme based c andthe for commercial bank clients than for investment bank clients. In other words, increasing firm size reduces the net yield of commercial bank undenNritten issues more than that of investment bank underwritten issues. Therefore, commercial banks are better off underwriting for large firms than for small firms. Based on our model specification, ceteris paribus, the beta coefficient differential ((31-132) should translate into a positive relation (-(B1-Bz)>0) of firm size and selection of commercial banks as underwriters. We classify as exogenous the selection based on the interactions between the publicly known characteristics of the firm and the identity of its underwriter. If we use only one net yield equation for both types of undenlvrlters, we are assuming there is no exogenous selection, that is, we are imposing the restriction B1: [32 ‘8. Therefore, regardless of underwriter identity, the bond price effect of firm size is the same. Firms receive different bond prices because they have different sizes; this has nothing to do with the identity of their undenNriters. Thus, an empirical model with only one net yield equation does not strictly follow from the theoretical literature. This inconsistency might explain why previous studies have been unable to provide a role for investment banks to exist and survive in and BPS regression for investment bank (IB) for the remaining paper. 1" In the paper of Puri (1996) and Gande et al (1997), they use the framework of Heckman’s two-step method and two-stage tobit model, respectively. The models consist of one probit selection equation and one bond pricing equation. They use the first-stage probit estimates to control the selection bias in the second-stage bond pricing regression. Therefore, their models can be viewed as a restricted version of our model that the ability of different types of underwriters in certifying public information of firms is the same, and the only difference between these underwriters is the private information, proxied by the probit estimates, which can be revealed only by the identity of underwriters. 21 ther: inves have: engag benefi isgpve Elyhi the pre-Glass-Steagall era when commercial banks were competing with investment banks more freely. Another advantage of this three-equation model is that, given that we do have selection between underwriters, the benefit of allowing commercial banks to engage in the securities unden/vriting business can be quantified. The gross benefit for firm i underwritten by commercial bank rather than by investment bank is given by the following equation: ¢(Zr) E . 1::1— .:X 7+0", (yZIl I ) yll rfl- -£1_(D(Z}’) Ty“ (11) The first term in equation (11) represents the expected mean net yield of commercial bank underwritten issues, had they chosen an investment bank as underwriter. The gross benefit for firm i underwritten by an investment bank rather than by commercial bank can be defined similarly. Theoretically the switching regression model can be identified if the independent variables are the same for the three-equation system, because the endogenous adjustment terms estimated from probit regression are nonlinear, thus the rank condition for identification can still be satisfied. However, if the adjustment terms are not nonlinear enough, then we may encounter serious multicollinearity problems at the second stage when the net yield equations are estimated”). Therefore, in the probit estimation, we use cash and reduction of long term debt as instrumental variables (IV) to improve the identification of our empirical estimation. In order to be a valid IV in the current study, the variable ‘9 See page 271 in Maddala (1983) for more discussions. 22 shoui no 8X finnc: should be related to the underwriter-choice decision, and at the same time, have no explanatory power on the yield of new bond issues after all other essential firm characteristics are controlled for”. 2° As it is discussed in Opler et al (1999), firm maintains a surplus of internal funds, it accumulates cash and pays back debt when it becomes due. Cash is simply negative debt. Therefore, both cash and reduction of long term debt are used to proxy the level of cash reserves of firms. 23 1.4 T corpor New Is insuffic comm? study th allowec have m the san and nor bOth iss and Cor from the The Usert n1 ‘0 2224 . 1.4 Data and Descriptive Statistics The data used in this paper consist of fixed-rate nonconvertible domestic corporate bond issues from the Securities Data Corporation (SDC) U.S. Debt New Issues database. Equity issues are not included in the study mainly due to insufficient sample size. There are only 15 common stock issues underwritten by commercial banks within the 12 months ended February 1997, according to the study by Bhargava and Fraser (1998). Although commercial banks have been allowed to underwrite corporate equity issues since 1989, the data are too few to have meaningful results. Therefore, we only use corporate bond issues during the sample period from January 1, 1991 to December 31, 1996. Only non-utility and non-financial firms are used in the analysis. To be included in the sample, both issue characteristics and firm characteristics must be available from $00 and Compustat databases respectively. Stock return data of issuers is collected from the CRSP Stock files. The initial data contains 2935 bond issues. After we delete issues without useful net yield, purpose of issue and maturity data, the sample size is reduced to 2224 observations. The requirements for calculation of volatility of stock return eliminates an additional 604 observations; those for cash, interest expense relative to operating income, sales growth, and total debt to total asset eliminate 57, 31, 82, and 14 issues, respectively. The market value of equity variable reduces another 55 issues from the remaining sample. Finally, missing data for equity trading volume and reduction of long-term debt variables eliminate 28 and 24 26 ct: AHva pnort are m reduct daily cl which meCR Detaile Th1 for eacl Present banks,i peood, ””18 of of “WE: COmme level. C 26 observations respectively. The final sample consists of 1327 observations”. All variables constructed from Compustat are measured at the end of the year prior to the bond offering. Market value of equity and trading volume of issuers are measured at the end of the month preceding the bond issue. The variable reduction of long term debt is measured in the year of bond issuance. Volatility of daily equity return is proxied by the variance of residuals from the market model, which is estimated over 120 trading days prior to the issuing date. The return on the CRSP value-weighted index is used to proxy domestic market returns. Detailed definitions of each variable are listed in Appendix A. The frequency of bond issues and summary statistics of selected variables for each year by type of underwriter during the period 1991 to 199622 are presented in Table 1.2. The proportion of bonds undenNritten by commercial banks, which is 4.2% in 1991, grows to 18.6% by 1996. Over the entire sample period, the average proportion is 13.9%. Based on a yearly comparison, client firms of commercial banks are not significantly smaller in size compared to those of investment banks. However, over the entire sample period, the average commercial bank client firm is significantly smaller by about $4 bn, at a 10% level. On the other hand, both mean and median issue amounts underwritten by 2‘ There are 33 observations with negative values of interest expense relative to operating income due to negative operating income; for these observations we have used zero to replace the negative value. 22 The frequency of commercial bank underwritten issues in 1996 is much lower than the number of transactions reported in (Bhargava and Fraser, 1998), mainly due to the fact that we only use industrial bond issues, and the heavy data requirement in our study reduces the sample size to some extent. 25 com onza: BPS) lower BPSs connnr thechfl butthe yields 0 undenw undenw the diffs invest” Charact Control] commercial banks are significantly smaller than those by investment banks even on a yearly basis, except the first year. During the whole sample period, the mean net yield (basis point spread or BPS) of commercial bank underwritten issues is 120.08, which is significantly lower than the 137.7 of investment bank underwritten issues. The medians of BPS show the same results as the means. The median of BPS is 71 for commercial bank clients and 91 for investment bank clients. A similar pattern of the difference in BPS is reported using pre-GIass-Steagall era data (Puri, 1996), but the univariate results are not enough to draw any conclusions. The lower net yields of commercial bank underwritten bonds could be the result of superior underwriting abilities, but it is also possible that commercial banks may choose to undenNrite for safer firms or firms with characteristics that reduce the BPS. Thus, the difference in BPS between commercial bank underwritten issues and investment bank underwritten issues is not comparable, unless the firm characteristics and the potential endogenous selection problem are formally controlled for. Markets segmented by size of issue23 are also compared in Table 1.3 to explore the possible regulatory distortion in the clientele of commercial banks. Commercial banks underwrite 20.8% of the issues in the small issue market, and only 7.7% of the issues in the large market. The size of issue underwritten by commercial banks is also significantly smaller than that by investment banks in both markets, whereas, the size of commercial bank clients in the small issue 23 We use the median size of issue (150 million dollars) of the full sample to separate the 26 market has no difference in mean and in median. In the large issue market, both mean and median of firm size are significantly smaller for commercial bank customers. Net yields (BPS), for commercial bank underwritten issues are significantly lower although the credit ratings are not significantly better in the small issue market. In the large issue market, the credit ratings of commercial bank clients are significantly lower, but the net yield is not significantly higher. The higher association of lower quality firms may imply that commercial banks are less able to retain higher rated firms in the large issue market. The credit ratings in Table 1.4 are categorized into 7 groups to examine possible specialization in underwritings on this dimension. The results are consistent with the theory proposed in Diamond (1991) that borrowers with credit ratings toward the middle of the range have a higher demand for bank monitoring. The effect of monitoring is also more valuable for the middle rated firms. Commercial banks do not undenivrite any issues for the highest and the lowest rating groups. The proportion of the sample undenrvritten by commercial banks is the highest for the A and Baa groups. The distributions of issuer credit ratings are significantly different at the 10% level. Basis point spreads are also significantly lower for the A and Baa groups that are underwritten by the commercial banks than that by investment banks, while there is no difference for the Aa, Ba and B groups. Interestingly, category B shows higher basis point spreads for commercial bank underwritten issues, although it is not statistically significant. If the perceived conflict of interest increases or the value of bank markets. 27 inonn inves oreve enoug rahngs conflb quesht monitoring diminishes as credit rating decreases when the issuer is in the non- investrnent grade category, then commercial bank association creates less value or even negative value for such a firm. When the negative impact is large enough, commercial banks will not underwrite for firms with extremely low credit ratings such as C or below. Therefore, these results are consistent with both the conflict of interest hypothesis and the low value of bank monitoring for questionable or inferior quality issues. 28 1.5 T onthe impos comps banklr conflic‘ The firs underw comme ability 0 InVeshg price (n: The beta Cor arldl .7 1 Thelnde rating, C; 1.5 Regulatory Distortion and Comparative Advantages of Underwriters The study of the determinants of underwriter selection in this paper is based on the certification ability of underwriters and the distortion of revenue limitation imposed only on commercial banks. In terms of certification ability, we test four competing but not mutually exclusive hypotheses. As stated above, they are the bank information advantage hypothesis, the bank relationship hypothesis, the conflicts of interest hypothesis and the bank information monopoly hypothesis. The first two represent the relative advantages of commercial banks as undenNriters, while the last two represent the relative disadvantages of commercial banks as undenNriters. Due to the 10 percent revenue limitation, the ability of commercial banks in handling large issue could be hampered. We then investigate the possible distortion by examining the relationship between bond price (net yield) and issue size as well as firm size. The results of the probit model estimation of underwriter selection and the beta coefficients of second stage BPS regressions are reported in Tables 1.5,16 and1.7 for the full sample, and the small and large issue markets respectively”. The independent variables in all the analyses are the same except for credit rating, cash, reduction of Iong-terrn debt, the interaction between dummy 2‘ In order to prevent unnecessary collinearity in estimating the BPS regressions for these subsamples, the explanatory variable, size of issue is dropped in the small issue market subsample, since the results in Appendix B2 show this variable does not explain the net yield of bonds in the small issue market. For the same reason, the endogenous adjustment terms are dropped in the large issue market. 29 variat: I exper | As choice rating t of long- empiric.i The rGillianc oDefatin rEgressir between andinter regreSSic term. The variables representing the intention to refinance bank debt and high interest expense”5 and the endogenous selection adjustment terms. As in Diamond (1991), the relationship between firm credit rating and the choice of underwriter is not linear. Firms with credit ratings in the middle of the spectrum tend to be associated with commercial banks. So, in the probit estimation, we use credit rating26 and non-investment grade dummy variable to capture this nonlinear relationship. However, in the second stage BPS regressions, we only use non-investment grade dummy to control the credit rating to avoid too much collinearity in the linear regression. Cash and reduction of long-term debt are the instrumental variables we used to enhance the empirical estimation”. The interaction between the dummy variable representing the intention to refinance bank debt and the indicator of high interest expense relative to operating income cannot capture the effects in the second stage BPS regressions too well. So we use a more continuous measure, the interaction between the dummy variable representing the intention to refinance bank debt and interest expense relative to operating income, in the second stage BPS regressions and report only the results of model specified with this interaction term. The endogenous selection adjustment terms are estimated from the first stage probit, and the variables are described in Appendix A. The second stage 25 The high interest expense indicator is one if the interest expense relative to operating income is greater than the median of this variable, 0 otherwise. 2" The assigned value of credit rating is 1, if the Moody’s credit rating for the bond issue is Aaa or Aa, the value is 2, if it is A or Baa, the value is 3, if it is non-investment grade. 27 See Section 1.3 for a detailed discussion. 30 BPS rem ON uncha 1.5.1 Itn mshkn this pr; this on. ODSEPV Smaller banks! be Obs banks' strateg the 10 S'eCtion reSJUIat tier then CE Further betWEe BPS regressions are also analyzed by alternative model specifications, which remove some insignificant independent variables with the results essentially unchanged. We report these additional results in Appendices B1 and B2. 1. 5.1 Regulatory Distortion of Commercial Bank Undenmr'tings It may be plausible to assume commercial banks have disadvantage in distributing the corporate securities they underwrite, since they were barred from this practice for 60 years. As an entrant to the market, they need to redevelop this crucial skill in order to distribute large issues effectively. However, we observe that the issue size managed by commercial banks became smaller and smaller over time during 1993 to 1995. This trend seems puzzling. If commercial banks gain experience through completing deals, then the opposite trend should be observed. One possible explanation of this trend would be that commercial banks possess unique advantages in underwriting for small clients, so they strategically position themselves in the small issue market. On the other hand, the 10 percent revenue limitation may be the cause of this phenomenon. In this section, we empirically explore whether the small client advantage or the regulatory distortion is the underlying reason for the above trend. If commercial banks possess distribution abilities similar to investment banks, then ceten's pan'bus, there will be no observed selection based on issue size. Furthermore, the effect of issue size on the bond prices should be the same between these two types of underwriters. However, the results in Tables 15,16 31 bankc dlofi: of the Thl undent condhi bsue_- ability ( and1.7 do not support this null hypothesis. In fact commercial banks show a significant disadvantage in handling large issues. The probit estimates on issue size in Tables 1.5 and1.6 indicate that commercial banks are significantly associated more with small issue than with larger issues. Besides, Table 1.7 shows that the beta coefficient of issue size for BPS regressions of commercial bank clients is highly significant and positive in the large issue market. However, all other estimates on issue size are close to zero for BPS regressions regardless of the identity of underwriter. The results demonstrate that a commercial bank has to sell the bond it underwrites at a lower price, as the issue size increases. Under current market conditions, commercial banks lose on the ground in dealing with large bond issue. Consequently, the clients of commercial banks suffer from the limited ability of their underwriters. This may cause under-investment of commercial bank customers. Contrary to the finding by Gande et al (1997), we do not find evidence that commercial banks facilitate smaller firms in gaining access to the capital market. In their paper, they derive the conclusion by examining the issue size instead of investigating the firm size directly. In fact, commercial banks can reduce net yield of bonds more than investment banks when the size of firm is larger. Based on the comparative advantage of commercial banks on firm size, they should underwrite more large firms than small firms. However, the probit estimates on firm size in Tables 1.5, 1.6 and1.7 fails to show this pattern. When issue size is also considered, we find that the inconsistency in firm size is due to commercial 32 quant mves' some the b. ofbo Wekl Unde unde itScli reDOr resz Appe aCroS COITIn an es banks being constrained to handle only small issues (because of their inability in handling large issue sizes). Since firm size and issue size are positively correlated, when one variable is restricted the other may be affected systematically. Thus, these results do not support the small clients advantage hypothesis. Besides the advantage of studying the pros and cons of different undenivriters, the application of the switching regression model allows us to quantify the benefits that different underwriters create. Therefore, we are able to investigate the effect of bank entry and regulation distortion at the micro-level, something which has not been done by previous research in this area. We define the benefits created by the chosen underwriters by the expected mean net yield of bond issue, had it chosen the unselected underwriter minus the observed net yield of bond issue. Thus this term will be positive if the net yield of bond issue underwritten by selected underwriter is smaller than that by unselected underwriters. It also means that the selected underwriter perform better to serve its clients than the counter group. The benefits presented in Table1.8 are estimated by using the results reported in Table 1.5. To check the robustness of the results, we also use the results reported in Appendix B1 to estimate the benefits and present them in Appendix B3. The benefits created by the selected undenrvrlters are analyzed across time, size of issue and credit ratings. The full sample results show that commercial bank entry created insignificant benefits for clients on average, with an estimate of 2.43 during the whole sample period. Only firms with credit ratings 33 in the middle range as a group show significantly positive benefits in Panel B of Table 1.8. The inefficiency of commercial bank underwritings could be driven by two factors. First, commercial banks were barred from underwriting for nearly 60 years. As new entrants to the security underwriting business, they need time to develop their underwriting expertise. Second, commercial banks were allowed to undenlvrite corporate securities again under regulatory restrictions. Therefore, we have a group of constrained underwriters competing with the unconstrained group. Thus, the benefits created by investment banks are significantly positive since they are “ahead” of commercial banks by 60 years and they are competing without constraints. In order to confirm the inefficiency that may be caused by the revenue limitation, we continue the analysis by splitting the sample into small issue market and large issue market and into two subperiods. years 1991 to 1993 and 1994 to 1996. We re-estimate the benefits for these four subgroups to accommodate the changes in different issue sizes and different entry stages of commercial banks. The results reported in Table1.9 indicate that bank-entry in the security underwriting business is beneficial to the commercial bank clients as a group. When we compare the magnitude of benefits created by the selected underwriters across different issue size markets, we find the magnitude is smaller in the large issue market than in the small issue market. This is consistent with the results in Tables 1.6 and1.7 that, overall, the selection of underwriters is less pronounced in the large issue market. However, the patterns of undenlvriting efficiency of commercial banks are different between markets. During the later sub-period (during 1994 to 1996), commercial bank underwritings demonstrate a significantly positive estimated benefit of 24.39 in the small issue market, whereas the opposite is observed in the large issue market. In the large issue market, all estimated benefits of commercial bank underwritings change from significantly positive to negative numbers except the issuers with middle credit ratings (A or Baa). However, we can only establish significant negative benefits among the best-rated (Aaa and Aa) small issuers. The results are consistent with the findings of Nanda and Warther (1998) that smaller firms, and those that issue securities less often and have lower credit ratings tend to be more loyal and pay higher fees. These are the “locked-in” clients. However, for these trapped clients, the inefficiency occurs at the later entry stage of commercial banks. Although bank entry is not beneficial to all issuers, we do observe that commercial banks improve their underwriting ability over time in the small issue market. The reduction in magnitude of estimated benefits for investment bank clients at a later period is consistent with the above notion. The smaller positive estimated benefits imply that the differences in underwriting abilities between commercial banks and investment banks become smaller from the viewpoint of investment bank clients. If there was no distortion in the economy, as time goes by, we should observe a similar phenomenon in the large issue market, and the market should move towards a better equilibrium with more firms teaming up with the “right” 35 underwriters and commercial banks improving their underwriting ability. Although we observe the above "moving towards equilibrium" phenomenon that the firms served by investment banks at later period are the ones can receive positive benefits, we cannot conclude that commercial banks improve their underwriting ability. The timing of observed inefficiency is consistent with the hypothesis of regulation constraints rather than that of lack of distribution network or expertise because commercial banks are entrants. In addition, the large coefficient of issue size estimated in the BPS regression for commercial bank clients in Table 1.7 points out the weakness of commercial bank underwritings in large issue market. Besides the above evidence on supporting the regulatory distortion, we consider two other minor modifications of the revenue limitation regulations in 1993 and in 1996. In 1993, the Federal Reserve Board allowed section 20 subsidiaries to use an alternative revenue test that was indexed to account for changes in interest rates since 1989. The shift in interest rates causes the eligible revenues of commercial banks to shrink, therefore, the base of eligible income used to calculate the revenue limitation is smaller even though the level of eligible and ineligible activities of commercial banks remains the same. Although the new indexed test is expensive and complicated to execute, five section 20 subsidiaries switched to the new measure”. This implied that these section 20 subsidiaries were operating close to the 10% revenue limit around that 2" See Order of Federal Reserve System, Docket no. R-0841, “Revenue Limit on Bank- Ineligible Activities of Subsidiaries of Bank Holding Companies Engaged in Underwriting and Dealing in Securities.” 36 perio 1993 I again the in the qr rangir oomrr Steag comm dollar 1 that c markel have d In was a l Operati will be disadVg period. This may explain why the issue amounts are relatively smaller in years 1993 and 1994. In 1996 the Federal Reserve Board amended the revenue limitation order again. The new order allows commercial banks to exclude the interest earned on the ineligible securities from the 10% revenue limit. The change would decrease the quarterly ineligible revenue of some section 20 subsidiaries by a magnitude ranging between 19% and 79%”. Not surprisingly, the issue amounts of commercial bank clients increased sharply in 1996. Compared to the pre-Glass- Steagall era, the market share of commercial banks is still small. In 1996, commercial banks underwrote roughly 14% of the bond market based on the dollar amount in our sample, while in 1929, Kroszner and Rajan (1997) report that commercial banks underwrote 45.4% of the market. The relatively smaller market share nowadays, is most likely the result of regulation constraints as we have demonstrated. In 1997, the Federal Reserve Board rescinded the original firewall, which was a set of 28 rules, and consolidated the remaining restrictions in a series of 8 operating standards”. At the end of 1996, the revenue limit was raised to 25%. It will be interesting to examine the effects of these regulation changes to see if the disadvantage of commercial banks in handling large issue under 10% revenue 2" See Federal Register, September 17, 1996, “10 Percent Revenue Limit on Bank- Ineligible Activities of Subsidiaries of Bank Holding Companies Engaged in Underwriting and Dealing in Securities,” volume 61(181): 48953-48954. 3° See Federal Reserve System Docket No. R-0958, “Bank Holding Companies and Change in Bank Control (Regulation Y); Amendments to Restrictions in the Board’s Section 20 Orders.” 12 CFR PART 22_5._ 37 limitation disappears and if the large issue market will move to a more efficient matching between underwriters and client firms. 1.5. 2. Advantages of Commercial Banks as Undem/riters The probit estimates of credit rating and non-investment grade in Tables1.5 and1.6 are consistent with the informational advantage hypothesis. Firms with lower credit ratings tend to select commercial banks as their undenivriters. In Table1.5, the variables related to the lnforrnation asymmetry problem are daily equity return volatility, equity trading volume, firm size, and Tobin’s q. The results for both daily equity return volatility and firm size are weak in supporting any hypothesis regarding certification ability of underwriters; we do not discuss these two variables further in this section. The association of commercial banks with clients that have low equity trading volume supports the information advantage of commercial bank hypothesis. The last variable used as a proxy for the information problem is Tobin’s q, which is also used as a proxy for investment opportunity in existing empirical finance literature. Both probit and BPS estimations show support for the information advantage and the bank relationship hypotheses rather than for the information monopoly hypothesis. The positive relation of Tobin’s q with commercial banks and the lower beta coefficient of BPS regression relative to the estimate of investment bank underwritten issues imply that commercial banks possess an advantage in solving the information problem and in serving the 38 financing needs of growing firms. Therefore, commercial banks may certify firms with higher Tobin’s q better than investment banks. Similar results are found in Houston and James (1996), indicating that among firms with public debt outstanding, the reliance on bank debt is positively related to the importance of growth opportunities, with bank information monopolies having less importance for these firms. They also find that the reliance on bank borrowing is decreasing in overall leverage, a result that we too obtain. Overall, the significant association of commercial banks with firms that are less risky, traded less frequently, lower rated, and having higher Tobin’s q supports the informational advantage and the bank relationship hypotheses. Besides the exogenous selection when firm public information interacts with the identity of its underwriter, the signs and magnitude of endogenous selection adjustment terms can reveal the unobservable nature of underwriter selection. In Table1.5, the estimated signs of adjustment terms are both negative, which supports the cherry-picking behavior of commercial banks. However, only the estimates for commercial banks in the full sample or in the small market are significant. This result implies that commercial banks do possess better unobservable ability that is valued by the market, which puts investment banks at a disadvantage in certifying the private information of their customers. Overall, there is no evidence of endogenous selection in the large issue market, whereas, commercial banks can cherry-pick firms in the small issue market. 39 1.5.3 Disadvantages of Commercial Banks as Undennm'ters One important concern regarding commercial banks engaging in security underwriting is the potential conflicts of interest. The variables used to investigate this issue are whether the proceeds are used to repay bank debt, leverage, interest expense relative to operating income, and its interaction with intention to refinance bank debt. As discussed in Kroszner and Rajan (1997), if investors are aware of the motives of an underwriter, in equilibrium the underwriter will be forced to issue securities that are less risky and questionable to avoid the price discount. The probit estimates of the dummy variable for intention to refinance bank debt and leverage are consistent with the above notion, indicating that commercial bank clients are less risky and refinance for bank debt less frequently. However, we do not find the support for this argument by the probit estimates on interest expense relative to operating income and the interaction between intention to refinance bank debt and high interest expense indicator. In the BPS equations, interest expense relative to operating income and its interaction with intention to refinance bank debt show large price discounts, especially for commercial bank clients. The effect is stronger in the small issue market but weaker in the large issue market. In Table1.5, the estimates of interest expense relative to operating income and its interaction with intention to refinance bank debt from the BPS regression for commercial bank underwritten issues are nearly triple compared to the same 40 numbers for investment banks. However, the BPS is lower when the purpose of issue is refinancing bank debt and the level of interest expense is low. Overall, we do not find investors use the intention to refinance bank debt as a proxy for potential conflicts of interest and impose a price discount when the undenivriter is also a commercial bank. Instead, the effects of conflicts of interest are demonstrated through interest expense relative to operating income and its interaction with refinance bank debt. Thus, we need to consider the beta coefficients of these three variables as a group when interpreting the effects of conflicts of interest. The variables used to test bank relationship and information monopoly hypotheses are volatility of daily equity return, Tobin’s q, sales growth, and profitability. Tobin’s q has been discussed previously with results that do not support the information monopoly hypothesis. The estimates of volatility of daily equity return, sales growth and profitability support the information monopoly hypothesis. Although the probit estimates are not significant in Tables1.5 and1.6, the estimates of BPS regressions indicate that commercial banks are at a disadvantage when underwriting for firms with high volatility of daily equity return, sales growth and profitability. For commercial bank clients, higher growth rates will increase BPS of bonds significantly with an estimate of 0.82 in Table1.5; conversely, for investment bank clients, the estimate is -0.06 (insignificantly different from zero). Increasing the daily equity return volatility increases the BPS of bond issues for the clients of both underwriters, however, the magnitude is tripled for commercial bank clients. 41 Theoretically, while high profit is a favorable characteristic of firms, we should observe profitability reducing the BPS of bonds. This is true for investment bank customers, but the estimate is close to zero and positive for the commercial bank clients. Although a bank relationship is less valuable for firms with high profits, it should not lead to a zero beta coefficient of BPS regression. The possible explanation is the benefit of high profit is cancelled out due to the bank’s monopoly power to share the profit with its client in the future. The effects are magnified in the small issue market but reduced in the large issue market. These results provide support of a hold-up problem of commercial banks. Due to the hold-up problem, commercial banks are less credible in underwriting for firms with high volatility of equity return, “past” growth31 and profitability. 1.5.4 The Performance Comparison between Commercial Banks and Investment Banks In general, investment bank clients as a group are better off staying with their own underwriters, while those switching to commercial banks are not necessarily better off. When the results in Tables 1.8 and 1.9 are compared across credit ratings, firms in the middle range of credit ratings that switch to 3‘ The results of Tobin’s q and sales growth are different, although we try to use them as the proxies for growth opportunities. However, Tobin’s q represents future growth, sales growth is realized past growth. The former requires better information technology to certify the message it tries to convey, the latter, however, may not be a good proxy for future growth, instead, the past growth seems to provide information similar to profitability but it is not a complete repetition, because after operating income is included, sales growth still possesses explanatory power in the BPS regression. 42 commercial banks are always better off, regardless of whether they are small issuers, large issuers, at the early stage or later stage of bank-entry. The results are consistent with the theory of Diamond (1991) that middle rated firms receive the most benefits from bank association. For firms with other credit ratings, the benefits are either insignificantly different from zero or significantly negative. The groups that suffer from the bank entry are high rated small issuers and low rated large issuers”. Another interesting observation in Table1.9 is that if we compare the results across subperiods, the estimated benefits for investment bank clients are all positive at later period, but not for commercial bank clients. The results are consistent with the explanation that as more firms that should be underwritten by commercial banks switched from investment banks, the firms remaining with investment banks were the ones receiving greater benefits of using the underwriting service of investment banks. However, the factors affecting the benefits created by commercial banks are much more complicated. At the early entry stage, commercial banks may have picked the firms from the top of the list, but at the same time, since they just started developing their underwriting ability, the two effects may cancel each other out. Similar effects may exist at the later entry stage, however the process is reversed, because banks pick firms with lower benefit potential while their underwriting ability improves. The 10 percent revenue limitation creates additional complications. Thus, at the later entry stage, the performance of 32 The result is marginal significant if one-tailed t-test is used. 43 commercial banks worsens in the large issue market. Although one may argue that the large issue clients could switch to investment banks, the switching cost may not be worth the benefit, especially for the clients with low credit ratings. We may then observe some inefficiency in the commercial bank undenlvritings. 1 .6 Conclusion We find that commercial banks do not actively engage in the small issue market voluntarily. In fact, based on their comparative advantage along the firm size dimension, they should be more active in underwriting for large firms. However, the 10% revenue limitation restricts their ability in handling large issues. We provide evidence that this distorted behavior of commercial banks observed in the security market during the sample period is the result of a regulatory restriction. This contributes to the observed inefficiency in the large issue market among the commercial bank clients at the later entry stage. In this paper, we examine the determinants of undewvriter selection, and establish the comparative advantages of commercial banks and investment banks. Commercial banks are superior in terms of information advantage and provide a better financing opportunity, thus they are associated with firms that have higher Tobin’s q, lower leverage, are traded less frequently and lower rated. The endogenous selection adjustment term also indicates that commercial banks can cherry-pick better customers. Due to concerns of conflict of interest, commercial banks clients incur larger price discounts if they have higher interest expense relative to operating income and when the purpose of issue is to repay bank debt. In addition, when firms with volatility of equity return, high past growth and profitability are associated with commercial banks, the potential bank monopoly power results in lower bond prices for these clients. 45 By using an empirical model that is consistent with theoretical work in this area, we are able to better quantify the benefits created by the selected underwriters for their client firms. The positive benefits created by investment banks demonstrate that they are valuable underwriters in the economy. The comparative advantages and specialization in security undenlvritings may also explain why investment banks coexisted with commercial banks in the pre-Glass- Steagall era, when both types of undenlvriters could compete freely. Therefore, this puzzle unexplained by previous studies is, we believe, resolved. Although the re-entry of commercial bank in the security underwriting business is not beneficial to all firms under the current regulatory and market environment, firms with middle credit ratings are better off on average. The distinct abilities of commercial banks and investment banks imply their coexistence is valuable to the economy, so clients at different segments have more choices and may be better served by different types of underwriters. 46 APPENDIX 1 TABLES OF ESSAY 1 47 Table 1.1 Summary of theoretical predictions regarding choice of commercial bank (vs. investment bank) to borrower’s risk (Volatility of stock return) (Total debt/total assets) (Interest expense relative to operatinjfincome) Hypothesis Prediction of Empirical proxy Predicted sign probability(bank) on empirical is: ‘ proxy Information Positively related Equity trading volume - Advantage to information asymmetry Volatility of stock return + Growth Opportunity + (Tobin’s q) (Sales growth) Firm size - (Market value of equity) Positively related Credit ratings to the value of (BEST) - bank monitoring (MID) + (LOW) - Positively related Firm size - to cost of collecting information Negatively related Risk - Positively related to borrower’s (unobserved) gualitya a Since the quality is unobserved, we do not have a proxy for this variable. However, the private information can be inferred by the underwriting decision of both undenlvriters. See Section 1.3 for a detailed discussion. 48 Table 1.1 (Cont'd) Hypothesis Prediction of Empirical proxy Predicted sign probability(bank) on empirical is: PTOXY Conflicts of Negatively related Use of proceeds includes - Interest when bank loan is repayment of bank loan to be repaid Negative related to Risk - borrower’s risk (Volatility of stock return) (Total debt/total assets) (Interest expense relative to operating income) Negatively related See the proxies in the The signs are to information information asymmetry opposite to asymmetry section of information those in the advantage hypothesis Information Advantage Hypothesis. Bank Positively related Cash and cash equivalent - Relationship to need for future bank financing Growth and investment Opportunity + (Tobin’s q) (Sales growth) Profitability (Operating income) - lnforrnation Negatively related See the proxies in the The signs are Monopoly to information information asymmetry opposite to asymmetry section of information those in the advantage hypothesis Information Advantage Hypothesis Negatively related Growth and investment - to potential hold-up opportunity problem (Tobin’s q) (Sales growth) Negatively related Profitability - to profitable firm (Operating income) Positively related Cash and cash equivalent + to firm required to keep compensating balances 49 03 on? on? mm? one 0m? 09 mxcmn EoEfioE. taco? .mww 5mm 33 :63 «to? on: 9.ch ESoEEoo Eo==E av .mEEovc: >5 cum mama. capo—2 Fméw.‘ Pods vmdt tam F node nvdom mad: 9.ch EoEuon. tam. mm «mm .09. at.» w .mm tam Km a-amm tau. 5 3.31. mxcmn _m_o..oEEoO ACE—=5 my hmzhémbc: >0 ®N_w gamm— 6mm: mfow mm. 5 Eton mfnm coda Nada afimm mxcmn EoEamoZ... Fwd? v99 mwdm 5.3. vméw modr _.N.v 9.ch _m_o..oEEoo ”>0 COECEOUCD mmzwfl *0 mmmfibmobmn— mv Z. N8 N5. m 3 mmm mmm mom mxcmn EoEumoE. va in vm om mm mm a 9.53 .mEoEEoO :3 acute/coca: meson. Co .3832 mam w- 59. mam? mam? 39. mag Nam? 59. 50> .69 833.53 coxoo__>> B 3338 E 8.55:6 m5 new $02 3 369 m_ memos. E 99:33:: So $9: 92 amnion mascots 9: Scream. mum 299:; m Co 569: new cmoE ccz>> EtamE oBEmano ho beacon. hammock .mj ho 29> oEm xo o5 56 259 m be cacao 29> 2cm 5 c5 .6 82an be m_ cacao £58 Emma 9:. Egon 22:5 5 333 Go o:_m> “9.5.: on. m_ use: Co 36 9F 53.305252: .3 new Emma» B octane. 9m menus econ Co mumoam ESQ mama new moum .mommucoouoa .2383: .30... abacutEoucz 3 new use» 3 mountouuflwsu E: can can». neon .0 33333 333.530 N.-. Sam... 50 .55. 5.5.62: 5 .2 5.525535. 5.55. .5555 3 5:5 .5 .3 55 5 E55555 2... .3. .. 35 on 55 5x. 53 v3 :5 3 55.55 25.5552... r... E 55 .55 5 .5n .55 55 55.55 5.5.5....50 >5 52:259.: 55:55. .0. 555.55 .505 5.55.5 5.55.2 p.23 35.53 3.53 55.53 35.53 N553 3.53 5x55 E58552: .5553 55...: 55.53 55.5 S 55.5 E 55. 3.. N55 9.55 5.558850 .3 55:259.: 55:55. 5.. 555.55 .555 5.555 55.2 35.: 55.5 3.5 55.5 vs: 55.5 55.5 9.55 25:552.. ...:.N5.5 $3.5 5nd 556 N55 .35 55.5 9.55 5.552.250 ”€5.55 8 5:25.52: >5 555 2...“. 5:55. 5.55.2 v53 35.: 5:5 V5.3 3.3 55.3 55.3 9.55 258.552.. 55.5 3:55.: 3.5 55.5 .. 5.5 5 3 .3 3.5 5x55 5.5.5.550 ”25...... 55 5.559.: .5 555 E._u. 5:55. 555. 555 T 353 553 553 .53 553 ~53 353 55> .355. «.3 2.3 51 Table 1.3 Descriptive statistics of bond issue by issue size market and by underwriter-type This table reports means and medians of issue size of bond, firm size (market value of equity), credit ratings, basis point spread of bond over the ex ante yield of US. Treasury security of comparable maturity, as well as the number of issue and percentage of issue by underwriter-type when the market is segmented into different sizes of issue. Credit ratings is 1 if the Moody’s credit rating for the bond issue is Aaa or Aa, the value is 2, if it is A or Baa, the value is 3, if it is non- investment grade. When mean and median of a variable are reported, the difference in means between two types of underwriters are tested by t-test and that in medians by Wilcoxon rank-sum test, respectively. The small issue market is defined as the new-issue bond market if the size of issue is less than the median of the issue size (150 million dollars). The large issue market is defined as the new-issue bond market if the size of issue is greater than or equal to 150 million dollars. Small Issue Market Large Issue Market Mean Median Mean Median Issue Size by Underwriter ($ million) Commercial banks 45.26*** 16.5“" 207.24*** 195*" Investment banks 79.02 100 265.8 229.15 Issuer Firm Size by Underwriter (3 billion) Commercial banks 5.75 2.99 7.35*** 3.86*** Investment banks 6.48 2.51 13.99 6.79 Credit Ratings of Issue by Underwriter: Commercial banks 2.08 2 2.17” 2** Investment banks 2.08 2 2.0 2 Issue Basis Point Spread by UndenNriter: Commercial banks 1 1 1 .75*** 71 *** 140.12 72 Investment banks 149. 36 98 128.79 85 Number of Issues Undenlvritten by: Commercial banks 130 54 Investment banks 495 648 Percentage of Issues UndenNritten by: Commercial banks 20.8 7.69 Investment banks 79.2 92.31 *, **, *** Significant at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels, respectively, for a two- tailed test. 52 Table 1.4 Issuer credit ratings distribution and basis point spreads by underwriter-type The basis points spread (BPS) is the premium of the ex ante yield spread of a bond over the ex ante yield of US. Treasury security of comparable maturity. The first column contains the proportion of the sample for each credit rating category, followed by the means and median of BPS for each credit rating category for the commercial bank undenNritten issues. Columns 4, 5, and 6 contain the same information as that in columns 1, 2, and 3 for investment bank undenlvritten issues. Test for difference in means is a two-tailed t-test. Test for difference in medians is a Wilcoxon rank-sum test. The last row in the table shows the chi-square test and p-value, with the null hypothesis being that the credit ratings distributions for issues undenlvritten by both underwriters are the same. Commercial Banks Investment Banks Moody’s Percentage Basis Point Spread Percentage Basis Point Spread Credit Ratings of Issue Mean Median of Issue Mean Median Aaa 0 1.84 50.67 44.1 Aa 7.61 52.99 53 13.3 55.52 50 A 47.83 57.37*** 55*“ 40.42 80.12 76 Baa 26.09 89.26“" 80*" 25.81 128.44 1 10 Ba 9.78 234.89 233 9.71 269.78 245 B 8.7 486.97 463 8.31 427.74 396 C or below a 0 0.61 346.77 275 Chi2(6)= 10.74; p-value = .097 *, **, *** Significant at the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels, respectively, for a two- tailed test. a This category includes non-rated bonds. 53 .nocaoE 9m $5 5965 notoqm: 6: 9m 259 EEmcoo new mQEEzc 2:3» 9: .8 $5623 of. .coszzmo Boa manage: 9: 80: 86833 2m mommfi cozoofim maocomonco o5 .9E8 2 com: 952 Eogmnfim wzocomoccm .oEooE @5980 o. 9:99 3598 $9.95 new Eon xcmn mocmccom E 6.9 c2692... 9: w_ 3598 $295.53 Ema oocmccom .2339 $5 so 569: 9: :9: Ema. m_ 9:85 93380 2 9.6.2 3598 5925 E _m>o_ o5 : F m_ cams B363 9: 633.9 >EEau m m_ .2865 $225 :9: 693550 o .53 xcmn mEExo mocmcco. o. m_ mama so 3093 05 t F m. 65 mfimtm> >583 m m. Emu xcmn mocmccom .938 .22 3 8233 353 so o2m> 8me man Eon ho o:_m> xoon 05 >9 Deacon m_ c 3.58 .mmsaméo o .099 E: .o 26.3 .0 mm m_ 96$ neon 05 .2 95m. :88 36022 on. a F m_ mama EoEsmo>Eéoz .mumzm EoEbmo>Eéoc m_ z a. .m m_ cams 9.: .95 .o < m_ z t .N 2 o:_m> o£ .m< .o mm< m. ozmm_ 6:03 9: .8 95$ :88 @3022 9: x F 2 95m. €20 .moamm_ coztzcouca Ema EmEumoE. 05 2:0 $63.05 @383 m5 .0 new m 3828 c. .933 53:53:: Ema _m_8mEEoo >Eo $63.05 29:3 9.: .v ncm m 2.828 c. .39-. so mo:_m>-a new mcofimmzmm. Ammmv 259% E8 £me ommsmficooom ho mEo_oEooo Son of: tone. 0 2 m 28:60 .xcmn EoEbmo>E cm m_ z a 0 new .xcmn _m_o_mEEoo m m_ 5:352: nmm. 9: t w m_ Smov ofimtg Eoncoaou 9: .F 5:28 c. .cozmnoo cozoofim 5.528;: 8 “mos-“ E mo:_m>-q new mmsmEzwo 505 9.: tone. 29.28 oz: “we: 9:. .353 ace—53>... >5 ..o 9.53 338853 2: >3 cautious: mason :o acacia 232. £23 ecu 2.2.023 Saracens: ho fleas—Egon 2.: no moan—cam. m... win... 54 9: :8 R2 80.8288 .0 .02 Ed 8d mm 88.2 2d 8-888 .. .. .. .. 8.: wood 38 5.98:0. :_ 8:88”. .. .. . . dvd «odd- $80-$88 3.2.280 Ed 8d- 8d fidd- .. . 58. E8828 88888 odd 8.va odd $.de Ed mudd- 888 58:82:82 . .. .. . odd «and 8:9 :85 omcoaxm ddd tdm 8d 8.8 . - .882. .. s8 .8: 8:88”. 55055 .. .. . .. 5d «ad 88:. :9: .. 38 3.58 858:8. dd 8.2 odd 8.8 8.: Sod- oE8:. 8.8888888 .882. 33%? 5d Rt- 8d 5.8- Ed Ndmd- 5.86:: 5.8 3.8: 8:88.: 8.: Rd- odd 8.:- ddd find. .88. :o 8.38. 8d 8.8- 8.: 8.8- ad dood- Ssam .0 8.9, 8.8563 8d 3d- 8d 3d. 8d wood 388 32858:. 8:980 8d 8.8 8.: 3d 8.: Ned a ”:53. Ed 8d- 8d 8d 2.: wood. Ed. :39... 8.8 odd 3.. 2d 8d dmd modd- 88. :o 3:22... 8d 8d 8.: 8d and mad- .2828: :58. 2.38 8 2.52.5 odd and 8d dmd- odd modd- 8522, 8.8.1.55 odd Ed 8d 8d- odd :3. e88 .9058“. .93 o:_m>-n_ mumEsmm mews-n. Bagsmw mag-n. 0662mm moi—28> Eoucoaons 3:8 .8282..QO 2:8 868558.85 :85 m6 035... 55 .:0:3.0:. 0:0 >9: .630... :0.:009 .0: 0:0 08:0. E0.0:00 ::0 00.883: >.:00> 9.. :0: 0908:00 0...- .:0:08:00 .50.: 08.0.9: 9.. 80:: 00:08:00 0:0 0000.: :0:00.00 03800080 9: 6:80 0. :00: 08:0. E08.03_:0 030:0mo::m 0800:. 05.9000 0. 02.0.9 00:00.0 .099:. ::0 E0: :80: 00:0::0m :0 8:0. :0..00:9:. 9: 0. 00:00.0 .099:_-.00: 80: 00:05:01 .0.:0.:0> 0:: :0 :0.:08 9: :0... :090. 0. 0800:. 0:..9000 9 02.0.9 00:00x0 .090.:. :0 .0>0. 0:. :. F 0. 03.0> 85.000 0:. .0_:0.:0> >883: 0 0. :0.00.::. .099:. :9... 00.3.9.8 o .50: E00 m::0.x0 00:05.0: 0. 0. 0300. :0 000930 9: :. F 0. .0... 0.00.:0> >883: 0 0. .00: :80: 00:0:_..0m 0.0000 .90. >0 :0:.>.: >..300 :0 03.0> .0808 03.: .00: :0 03.0> 0.00: 9: >0 :0:.-.0: 0. 0 0.500.- .00.2:9:0 o .:0.0: .0: :0 30.9. :0 0m. 0. 0300. ::00 9: :0: m::9 ..:90 0.>:00.2 9: :. F 0. 0:9: E08.00>:.-:0z 0:9: E08.00>:.-:0: 0. .. :. .m 0. 03.0> 9: .00m :0 < 0. .. :. .N 0. 03.0> 9: .90. :0 00< 0. 0300. ::0: 9: :0: 0:..9 ..:90 0.>:00.2 9: :. F 0. 0::9 ..:90 .00300. :0...:.s:0::3 E0: E0888. 9: 2:0 00:20:. 0.0800 9: .o ::0 m 0:83.00 :. .00300. :0:.:2:0::3 E0: .0.0:08800 >_:0 00:20:. 0.0800 9: .v ::0 m 0:83.00 :. ..09-. :0 003.0?0 ::0 0:0.00909 Amdm. 0:00:00 .500 0.00: 0m0.0-::0000 :0 0E0.0.::000 0.9. 9: :009 o 9 m 0:83.00 2:00 808.008. :0 0. .. :. o ::0 2:00 .0.0:08800 0 0. 8.88083 :00. 9.. :. F 0. Emu: 0.:0.:0> 80::000: 9: .F :83.00 :. 80:03.00 :0..00.00 6.88083 :0 .00.-. :0 0020?: ::0 00:08:00 .590 9: :80: 0:83.00 02,. .9: 9.... 90:0..0: 85.8 cm: 0300. :0 0N.0 :0.:08 9: :9: 000. 0. 0300. :0 0~.0 9: :. .9.:08 ::0: 0300.-:50: 0F: 00 85:0: 0. .0808 0300. ._080 9. :- .080: 808.008. :3 :o 0:80: 3.908800 0:. >0 00...:8083 0.80: :0 0:00:00 8.0.: 0.00.. 80 80:00.00 :0:_::s._0::3 :o 9:088:90: 05 :0 00:08.:0m ”.0808 0300. __08m 0... 030... 56 000 00: 000 08.020000 :0 .02 00.0 00.0 0: 00:00.00. 00.0 N0.00000: - - - - - . .000 80:000. 0. 0000000: - .. - . 00.0 90.0 2000-00000 0:00.500 00.0 00.0 00.0 000.1 00.0 000.0- 5:0. 0.0000200 0000000000 00.0 00.00: 00.0 00.00 0:.0 :000- 000:0 205005.002 - . - - 00.0 0:00 0000: :.00:0 00:00x0 00.0 9.00 0:.0 00.00 .. - 00:00:. - .000 .000 0000000: 5:00:05 - - - - 00.0 000.0 00:00:. 00.: - .000 .000 0000000: 00.0 00.0: 00.0 00.00: 00.0 00:0 00:80. 0000002000030 00:00:. :0.:0.:0> 00.0 00.00- 0:.0 00.00- :00 000.0- 8:00.05. .000 0.000 0000000: - - . - 00.0 000.0- .0000. :0 00.0.03 00.0 00.00- 00.0 0:. :0- 00.0 000.0- 00.000 :0 00.0.: 000503 00.0 00.0- 000 00.0 0:0 000.0- 0.0000 0.2.0880. 0:00:90 00.0 00.0: 00.0 00. :- 00.0 000.0 0 0.0.00: :00 ::.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 0000. 3:00. 530:0 00.00 00.0 00.: 00.0 0:: 00.0 000.0 0000. :0 0.5.0.2 00.0 00.0 00.0 9.0: :00 000.0- 0.000.000 0:30: 2.00 :0 0...:0_0> 00.0 :0 00.0 9.0- 00.0 000.0- 00:20:, 00.00:: 2.0.00 00.0 :00 :00 9.0- 00.0 :00. 0.0000 0.20000 .06: 03_0>-n. 908:0m. 03_0>-n. 908.:0m. 03.0?0. 908.:0m 00.00.:0> ::0::000::. 0.000 2080900000 0.000 0.205.000.000 000:: m... 030:. 57 00020:. 0:0 >00. 0030.: 09:009 .0: 0:0 08:0: 80.0:00 0:0 00.883: >_:00> 9.. :0: 00:08:00 9. .- .:0..08.:00 :.00:0 009099.: 0... 80:: 00:08:00 0:0 0000.0 :0..00.00 03800008 9: .9800 0. 0003 08:9 808.03.:00 030:0000:m 0800:. 02.9000 0: 02.0.0: 00:00x0 .0908. 0:0 .000 800 00:02:00. :0 8:0. 8:00:08. 9: 0. 00:00.8 8998.800 .800 00:08:00 .0.00.:0> 0.0. :0 :0.:08 9.. :0... :090. 0. 0800:. 0:..9000 0. 02.0.0: 00:00x0 .0908. :0 .08. 0:. :. F 0. 03.0> 00:0.000 9: .0.00.:0> >883: 0 0. :900.0:. .0908. 00.: 00.8080 0 ..000 .800 m::0.x0 00:0:_:0: 9 0. 0300. :0 0000:30 9.. :. F 0. :0:. 0.00.:0> >883: 0 0. .000 .800 00:05:00. .0.0000 .90. >0 000.>.0 >:.300 :0 03.0> .0808 03.0 .000 :0 03.0> 0.000 9: >0 00::00 0. .0 08.00... 00.8080 0 .099 .0: :0 30.00 :0 0m 0. 0300. 0:00 9.. :0: 08:0: :.00:0 0.>000$. 9.. :. F 0. 009m .:08:00>:.-:0z .0090 .:08:00>:.-:0: 0. .. :. .m 0. 03.0> 9.. .00m :0 < 0. :. :. .N 0. 03.0> 0:. .0< :0 00< 0. 0300. 0:00 9: :0: 0:..9 :.00:0 0.>000.>. 0:. :. F 0. 02.0: :.00:0 .00300. :0:..:>.:00:3 .800 808.008. 9.. >80 00020:. 0.0800 9: .0 0:0 0 0:83.00 :_ .00300. :0:.:2:00:3 800 .0.0:08800 >.:0 00020:. 0.0800 0:: .0 0:0 0 0:83.00 :_ :00.-. :0 003.0>-0 0:0 0:0.00909 :w0m. 0:00:00 8.00 0.000 0090-08000 :0 080.0508 0.00 9.. 8009 o 0. 0 0:83.00 2:00 808.008. :0 0. .. :. 0 0:0 .800 .0.0:08800 0 0. :0..:800:3 000. 9: :. F 0. Emu. 0.00.:0> 800:0000 9: .F :8200 :. 80:03.00 :0..00.00 :0..:>>:00:3 :0 .09-. :0 003.0>-0 0:0 00.08.:00 :.00:0 0:. 8000: 0:83.00 02:. :0:... 0:... .9080 :0....8 003 0300. :0 00.0 :0.:08 9: 0. .0300 :0 :0... :9090 0. 0300. :0 00.0 9: :. .0808 0:00-2.0: 0:. 00 00::00 0. .0808 0300. 00:0. 00.: .0800 808.008. >0 :0 0800 .0.0:08800 00. >0 88:800.... 00:00 :0 0:00:00 8.00 0.000 0:0 0:980:00 :0:.:3:00:3 :0 0800.80.00 0... :0 00:08:0m 30808 0:00. 090.. h... 0.00... 58 000 .0 NE 08002080 :0 .02 0:0 2.0 0.: 00:00.3: :0 N0.0.0.0000 - .. - .. 00.0 000.0 .000 5.0.002 c. 8.00000 - - .. - 3.0 000.0 3000-90000 0.2.0000 - - - - 2.0 000.0 .50: 205.0000 88000000 00.0 00.03 00.0 00.00. 00.0 000.0. 000:0 505002802 - - - - 00.0 0.0.0 08:0: :.00:0 00:00x0 00.0 00.00 0.0 00.00. - .. 000.5 - .000 0.00.. 080800 5.00.0... .. .. .. - 00.0 {0.0 000.0. 00.: - .000 0.000 00:00:00 00.0 00.00 000 0:00- :00 000.0- 058:. 05.008.00.090 .0003. .0.00.:0> .00 00.0- «.0 00.0. 00.0 00.0- 5:00.05. .000 .000 00:00:00 .00 00.0 8.0 00.00. 3.0 000.0- .0000. :o 00.0.03 00.0 00.00- 00.0 00.21 00.0 03.0- .0500 :0 020:, 00.05.03 .00 :.v. .- 000 .0. 7 00.0 000.0 0.0000 0.20580. 05.0000 .00 00.0 00.0 3.00 00.0 30.0- 0 0.50.: 00.0 2.0- 00.0 00.0 00.0 000.0 2:00. 530:0 0200 00.0 K... 0:0 00.. 00.0 0.0.0- 0:00. :0 0.5.05. 00.0 00.0 00.0 00. 7 0.0 000.0- 0.000.000 530: 0.000 :0 0....0_o> 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 «0.0 000.0- 0522, 00.00:: 0.000 00.0 000 00.0 00.0- 00.0 000.0- 0.0000 0.05000 0.0» 03.0>-n. 0:08.:0m. 03.0>-0 0:08.:0m. 03.0>-n. 0.08..0m. 00.00.:0> .:0::0000:. 0.000 2060080000 0.000 0002500000 5... 0.00... :.00:0 59 Table 1.8 Gross benefit for firm using the service of chosen underwriter rather than that of unchosen underwriter. The gross benefit is defined as the expected mean net yield (BPS) of bond issues, had they chosen the unselected underwriter minus the observed net yield of bond issues. The benefit estimated in column 1 (below the heading of Commercial Bank Clients) is the predicted BPS of commercial bank client by using the estimates of investment bank BPS regression reported in Table 1.5 minus the original BPS of commercial bank client. Hence, the benefit in column 3 is estimated in the same way. The p-value of t-test is reported, the tested null hypothesis is the gross benefit is equal to zero. Panel A. Gross benefit of full sample and by subperiods. Commercial Bank Clients Investment Bank Clients Years Benefit P-value Benifit P-value 1991-1996 2.43 0.63 164.62 0.00 No. of observations 184 1143 1991-1993 -0.65 0.91 171.31 0.00 No. of observations 66 664 1994-1996 4.15 0.56 155.35 0.00 No. of observations 118 479 Panel B. Gross benefit by credit ratings Commercial Bank Clients Investment Bank Clients Credit ratings Benefit P-value Benefit P-value Aaa or Aa -16.22 0.02 181.08 0.00 No. of observations 14 173 . A or Baa 11.98 0.00 156.88 0.00 No. of observations 136 757 Ba or below -28.08 0.26 178.79 0.00 No. of observations 34 213 Panel C. Gross benefit by the issue size (in million dollars) Commercial Bank Clients Investment Bank Clients Issue Size Benefit P-value Benefit P-value >= 150 -3.7 0.74 170.79 0.00 No. of observations 54 648 < 150 4.98 0.36 156.55 0.00 No. of observations 130 495 60 hm v. an N. mcozmzmmno ho .02 and mod? ..o.o mmdm cod and? mad 3.91 26.8 .0 mm mmm 2 SF vm macsmzomno .0 .oz 006 omhm- 3.0 NNdP cod mméor mNd mad mam .5 < mm v mm v mcostmmno “—0 .02 mod 3...” :.o 3.9 00.0 mwem omd N...NN- m< .o mm< Fov Pm mom mv mcoszmmno .0 .oz cod omém- cod mmém cod m v .8? vmd om? 3:29 __< m:_m>-n. Eocmm m:.m>-n. Emcmm o:_m>-n. Eocom o:_m>-n. Eocom 3:33. .690 9:95 3:0..0 3:25 3:25 .53 E9532: .53 3.056800 xcmm 2.958%. .53 3.055800 $me 2.3. 35.. reins. 25m. =me .32 2 Saw actsn macaw. «:38 .3 «cocoa 39.0 .< .25“. .93 o. :33 m. Emcee 306 oz. m. £8509... =3: no.8. on. .notoao. m. 69.. .6 m:.m>-a on... .notoam. .0: 9m 20.893. mam 32% 9.2.8 co__..E 0...... o. .33 .0 cm... .235 9:2. mum 5.3 333. 3.3.2... $.me 03mm. mmcm. on... .33 06mm 9: c. noumEzmo 9m m o. m 9.828 :. mEocmn m5 .ooco... .Em_.o xcmn 6.96668 .0 mam 3598 on. 95.8 $5.8 8...? cm? cm... $9. 6me 38. =me 5,. 9.392 56369 69 29m... :. cotoao. .86QO9 mam xcmn E68695 kB $66.60 9: 9%: >9 Em=o xcmn 3.05888 .0 mam 8.0.8:. o... m. .3535 xcmm _m_o.oEEoo .o 9.699. o5 26.3. r :828 5 868.60 50:2. 9: .333. econ .6 Be... am: 82830 on. 35:. 53.53:: 62023:: on. 5on >9: no: .333. neon .o .95. 2o... .0: come vouooaxo 9: mm noccou m. Emcee $20 on... anotoansm .3 3qu 03mm. 3.5. can 3qu came. =2.» .5. Butane—cc: 535:: .o as: 55 .352 3553:: nonoso .o 3.23 05 9:»: SE so. «cocoa «no.0 m... 2an 61 00 I. _.0.0 50.00 0N0 V0.0- v0w 0N P00 dev 00.0 mmém 0N N n00 0V0? 00.0 50.3- tum mm 00.0 00.3 050 00.0.. 03.970 2.330 03.0>-n. E030 Nv NP 5.0 03K .30 00.00 00? 00 00.0 5.00 00.0 00.0w hm v 00.0 00.50 #00 5.90- NmN 00 00.0 5.: 00.0 mméw 03.03. Emcmm 03.030 50:00 06:0 38:0 .30 EoEummé. xcmm .0.03EE00 35:0 98:0 .30 .3536. 0.500 .0.03EE00 30.6.2 033. 040.00.. 30:05. 0:00. .680 30.620000 6 .02 26.00 6 00 30.002030 .0 .oz 30 .0 < 30.620000 6 .oz m< .o mm< 30.620000 6 .oz 85.9 __< 00:30.. 0.00.0 .83 o. 32 0550 00:02 0.09.0 .3 Enema 320 .m .25. .0280. 0.. 03¢ 62 ESSAY; C EMPEtTITIQN AND COALITION AMONG UNDERWRITERS: THE ENTRY STRATEGY OF CQMMERCIAL BANK§ IN 115 POST-SECTION 20 ERA 2.1 Introduction During the recent debate over whether or not to repeal the Glass-Steagall Act, investment banks have been the major opponents of the repeal. Although investment banks have competed fiercely with commercial banks in the legislative arena, commercial bank entry into security undenNritings has been accommodated to some extent. Commercial banks have enteredthis market as co-managers through participation in investment bank lead syndicates. This particular undenivriting form accounted for only 10 percent of corporate bond issues in 1991, but soared to 38 percent by 1996. During the same period, commercial bank-lead syndicates underwriting bond issues increased from 4.2 percent to 18.7 percent. It is puzzling as to why commercial banks have not competed for the lead manager roles more aggressively, having cooperated with investment banks twice as much as they have competed. Even more puzzling is why investment banks have not more actively deterred entry by excluding commercial banks from participating in syndicates. Including issues co-managed with investment banks, commercial banks have participated in 56.4 percent of the new bond issues in 1996. Although prior research has examined the underwriting activities of commercial banks when 63 they have led underwriting syndicates”, the role of commercial banks as junior co-managers has yet to be examined. In this paper, we investigate the economic rationales driving coalitions between commercial and investment banks. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper examining the economic functions and effects of commercial banks as co-managers in security underwritings. Financial markets are often characterized as possessing an oligopolistic structure. Anand and Galetovic (1997) show that interrnediation markets are natural oligopolies, with entry being accommodated as long as cooperation is feasible. In this type of market, it may be beneficial for firms of various abilities to collude in the market. For security underwritings, it is a common practice to form syndicates among underwriters“. We would like to examine whether the coalitions among commercial banks and investment banks are driven predominantly by the industry market structure or some potential benefits of cooperation amongst underwriters. lf coalitions are driven predominantly by the oligopolistic market structure, i.e. if commercial banks act as perfect substitutes for investment banks in the syndicates, we should not observe any systematic pattern of coalition formation. Thus, the new form of underwriting activities would not differ from the existing investment bank lead-syndicates that commercial banks do not participate in. Following this line of reasoning, the choice of entry mode of commercial banks, 33 See Ang and Richardson (1994), Puri (1994), Puri (1996), Gande et al (1997), Song et al (1999) for empirical results in this area. 3‘ As stated in Eccles and Crane (1988, p.92), "The most visible ties among investment banks are the syndicates formed to underwrite and distribute a security offering." They report that the top six investment banks lead-managed 6,327 domestic security issues (excluding tax-exempt issues) from 1984 to 1986, over sixty percent of these deals were 64 either lead- or co-managing the syndicates, should not depend on the comparative advantages of commercial banks in different segments of the market. The percentage of commercial bank lead-managed issues relative to that of co-managed issues should only depend on the overall market power of commercial banks. However, Song (1999) find that commercial banks and investment banks represent two distinct types of underwriters. Commercial banks possess informational advantages over investment banks due to their loan monitoring and transactional activities with clients (Fama, 1985). Association with commercial banks also provides clients with better financing opportunities in the future (See, for example, Holland, 1994; James 1987). However, these benefits do come with costs. The dual role of commercial banks as both lenders and underwriters creates the potential for conflicts of interest. For instance, a commercial bank may misrepresent information about its clients by overstating clients' prospects. They could then underwrite these "bad" loans, using the proceeds to repay bank debt (See Kroszner and Rajan, 1997; Gande et al, 1997). Additionally, the same informational advantages may give commercial banks a temporary information monopoly over the clients' private information, allowing banks to appropriate firrns' future profits (Rajan, 1992; Sharpe, 1990; Greenbaum et al, 1989). In addition to the above differences between commercial and investment banks, Song (1999) find that the ability of commercial banks in distributing large issues is hindered by a revenue limitation35 imposed only upon them. This co—managed by another top-six investment banks. 35 The revenue limitation was set at 5 percent in 1987, was increased to 10% in 1989, 65 regulatory restriction constrains the amount of corporate issues commercial banks can underwrite by limiting the revenues generated from certain in-eligible security activities to 10 percent of the total revenues of section-20 subsidiaries36. Combining these two types of undemriters with complementary abilities could create better underwriting services. A similar positive effect is identified by Mohanram and Nanda (1998) in their joint ventures study. They find that the stock market reacts positively to joint ventures that involve pooling of complementary resources. In this paper, we address the question of whether coalitions between commercial and investment banks are motivated by economic incentives. We do so by testing the hypothesis that coalition arrangements of commercial and investment banks mitigate disadvantages of both types, yielding higher bond prices for their clients. In other words, we argue that the cooperation is motivated by mutual benefits. When an investment bank is the lead underwriter and a commercial bank participates as a co-manager, we define this new structure as a Hybrid syndicate. The syndicates led by commercial banks are defined as CB-Lead syndicates”. Those coalitions that do not include any commercial banks are referred to as Pure/B syndicates. and was raised again to 25 percent in 1996. See Federal Reserve System, Docket No. R-0841, "Revenue Limit on Bank-Ineligible Activities of Subsidiaries of Bank Holding Companies Engaged in Underwriting and Dealing in Securities." 36 See JP Morgan & Co. Inc, The Chase Manhattan Corp., Bankers Trust New York Corp., Citicorp, and Security Pacific Corp., 75 Federal Reserve Bulletin 192 (1989) (hereafter "1989 Order") for discussions on the regulatory environment that commercial banks are allowed to underwrite corporate securities. The section 20 subsidiary is the organizational form in which commercial banks are permitted to conduct the ineligible security activities. Ineligible activities refer to those not permitted before the relaxation of Glass-Steagall Act in 1989. 37 Commercial bank lead syndicates may or may not have other investment banks participate as co—managers. Although commercial banks may also cooperate with other commercial banks as a fourth type, the sample size representing only 2.2% of the bond 66 When testing the above hypothesis, we also focus on the role that lead managers play in alleviating the moral hazard problem, i.e. the potential conflicts of interest inherent in commercial bank security underwritings. The literature provides both theoretical and empirical support for this problem. Pichler and Wilhelm (1998) provide a monitoring role for the lead undenrvriter to improve incentives and mitigate the moral hazard problem of syndicate participants. Nanda and Yun (1997) find that lead managers share a larger proportion of the damage to reputation arising from an unsuccessful offering. Jain and Kini (1999) find evidence consistent with the demand for lead underwriter monitoring in initial public offerings. In the context of this paper, investment banks are not subject to the aforementioned conflict of interest problem faced by commercial banks. They should be more credible in certifying security issues when the purpose of an issue is to repay bank debt and when the level of interest expense is relatively high. Thus, we test whether the reputational concerns of an investment bank will alleviate concerns by the market for conflicts of interest. We propose and find evidence that the Hybrid syndicate serves this purpose. Despite disadvantages it has in underwriting for large issues and for issues with higher potential for conflicts of interest problem, commercial banks are found to possess better abilities in serving clients with certain attributes, such as firms with middle credit ratings38 (Song, 1999). It would be implausible for commercial banks to not take advantage of their superior abilities when they expand into issues, is too small to conduct multivariate analysis. For this analysis, the data is lumped in with other commercial bank lead syndicates. Thus, we focus our discussions on the three types of syndicates mentioned in the text. 3" The issues with middle credit ratings are those with Moody's ratings of either A or Baa. 67 these segments of the market, given that lead managers gain a larger share of the proceeds. Thus, we hypothesize that commercial banks strategically select their entry mode - leading the syndicate or participating as a co-manager - based on their strengths in different segments of the market. Using a sample of 1327 corporate bond issues from 1991 to 1996, we examine how issuing firms select among these three syndicates and how hybrid syndicates are different from CB-Lead and PurelB syndicates in terms of their underwriting abilities. We also analyze the performance of syndicates by subtracting the net yields of bond issues that selected syndicates obtain for their clients from predicted yields of unselected syndicates for the same clients. We find that in circumstances when the coalition arrangement is less beneficial to the commercial banks, they behave more aggressively in the market, having a higher tendency of choosing to lead a syndicate rather than to just participate in it. In the small issue market, where commercial banks display less distributional disadvantages, commercial banks lead-managed three times as many bond issues as they underwrote in the large issue market. They cooperate with another lead investment bank half as often in the small issue market as they do in the large issue market. Similar aggressive behavior is observed when commercial banks underwrite for firms with middle quality. They lead-underwrite a higher percentage of bond issues in the middle quality segment than in the high and low segments. These results support the hypothesis that commercial banks strategically select their entry modes. 68 We also find that the hybrid syndicate is distinctly different from both CB- Lead syndicates and PurelB syndicates on many dimensions. Clients of hybrid syndicates tend to be large issuers but not large firms. Hybrid clients are more profitable, have lower leverage, and are less likely to have an informational asymmetry problem. The purpose of their issues is more likely to be refinancing bank debt. The superiority of a hybrid syndicate is demonstrated through its ability to achieve higher bond prices for different clientele. Most of the beta coefficients in the net yield equation for hybrid clients fall between those of CB-Lead and PurelB syndicates. These estimates tend to fall closer to estimates of one or the other type of syndicate. The hybrid coefficient estimates on leverage support the informational advantage argument due to the involvement of commercial banks. Meanwhile, the involvement of investment banks in the hybrid syndicate alleviate part of the informational monopoly problem inherent in CB-Lead syndicates, as demonstrated by the estimates on sales growth and operating income being closer to those of PurelB syndicates. In addition, there are synergies with regards to volatility of equity return and Tobin's q. The hybrid estimates of the net yield equation for these two variables are the smallest of any group. Hybrid estimates of the net yield equation on equity trading volume and firm size resemble the averages of the other two parties. However, the hybrid syndicate performs the worst in the area of maturity of issue, with the estimate being the largest among the syndicates. Although both 69 CB-Lead and PurelB syndicates demonstrate cherry-picking ability39 over hybrid syndicates, there is no endogenous selection bias identified for hybrid syndicates. One possible explanation is that hybrid clients are the group with less of an informational problem. Thus, the identity of a syndicate can not provide additional value when all exogenous characteristics of firms have been considered. Overall, we find that the hybrid structure can preserve the advantages of commercial banks while mitigating many of their disadvantages. By cooperating with an investment bank, which lead-manages the bond issue, potential conflicts of interest of commercial banks can be reduced. The reputation of an investment bank and the more remote distance between lending and underwriting activities make the certification of the hybrid form more credible. Therefore, hybrid client firms that issue bonds for the purpose of refinancing bank debt will suffer less of a price discount than commercial bank-lead customers will. We provide evidence that the hybrid structure is a superior organizational form for many firms under current regulatory and market conditions. However, the existence of client switching costs enables undenrvriters to have temporary monopoly power over their clients. Not all of the customers have the privilege of enjoying better syndicate services. Consistent with the characteristics of client firms mentioned before, hybrid clients tend to have less informational asymmetry problems, and, thus, lower switching costs. 3" The cherry-picking ability refers to the informational advantage or unobserved ability of underwriters possess in that they are able to select clients they can serve better among firms with the same public known characteristics. 70 Our analysis of gross benefits, in terms of net yield differentials of bond issues, achieved by a chosen syndicate versus an unchosen syndicate supports the previous discussion. In the eyes of PurelB clients and most of the CB-Lead clients, the hybrid structure is a preferred choice. However, due to the existence of switching costs, these firms are still retained in less favorable syndicates. Among the three segments of issuing firms - high, middle, and low quality40 - middle quality firms that are lead managed by commercial banks are the only group which do not prefer the hybrid syndicate. Middle quality firms are better off staying with a CB-Lead syndicate than switching to the hybrid form. The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2.2 presents a review of the literature on entry of commercial banks into different financial markets and coalitions among underwriters. Section 2.3 describes the data and summary statistics. Section 2.4 discusses the entry strategies of commercial banks. Section 2.5 describes the characteristics of Hybrid syndicates in comparison to the other two syndicates. Finally, Section 2.6 concludes the paper. ‘° High quality firms are those with Moody’s credit ratings of Aaa and Aa; middle quality firms are those with A and Baa ratings; low quality firms refer to those with Ba or below. 71 2.2 The Literature on Bank Entry Strategies and Underwriting Coalitions Deregulation in the banking industry has provided numerous opportunities for commercial banks to expand their scope of operations. Bhargava and Fraser (1998) find positive abnormal returns for commercial banks when the Federal Reserve Bank began authorizing commercial banks to provide limited forms of security undenrvritings“. However, Bhargava and Fraser found that market reaction to increased securities undenrvriting powers in 1989 was negative”. Nonetheless, the expansion of commercial banks into security underwritings has grown rapidly since 1987. As of February 1, 1999, there were 51 section 20 subsidiaries. Among them, 41 were also authorized to conduct Tier II powers, while 2 were limited to underwriting corporate debt issues“. Boot et al (1998) propose a theoretical framework to explain the expansion of scale and scope in banking as an optimal strategy. They do so in an environment of "strategic future skills uncertainty", where it is not known whether the bank has the skills to compete effectively in new markets. In contrast to merging with an investment bank, adding a section 20 subsidiary allows commercial banks to acquire superior information regarding its underwriting ability and to ascertain whether it has the skills to compete in the ‘" In 1987, three bank holding companies were granted the power to underwrite municipal revenue bonds, private mortgage-backed securities, commercial paper and consumer—receivable-related securities. These powers have come to be known as "Tier I section 20 powers". See Citicorp, JP. Morgan & Co., and Bankers Trust New York Corp, 73 Federal Reserve Bulletin 473 (1987)(hereafter "1987 Order"). ‘2 The corporate security underwriting powers allowed in the 1989 Order have become known as "Tier II section 20 powers." ‘3 For the list of section 20 subsidiaries, see "Section 20 Secruities Subsidiaries." 72 new business without an excessive up-front investment. However, due to current regulations, adding a section 20 subsidiary is the only feasible method for banks to enter the security underwriting business“. Given that commercial banks have entered the security undenrvriting business, they face two choices - competing or cooperating with investment banks. Since lead-managers may grab a large share of the underwriting compensation and build reputation for future underwriting business, it seems reasonable to assume that commercial banks would compete more aggressively in acquiring the lead-underwriter role when they possess stronger market power. Conversely, when they are a smaller player in a given market, it seems rational for them to cooperate with others who may complement their weakness. In the following paragraphs, we explore possible circumstances under which commercial banks may need to cooperate rather than to compete. Kanatas and Qi (1998a) compare the level of information production and the amount of a client firm's investment in specialized versus integrated institutions. They find that the differences depend on the extent of borrower moral hazard, and the size of information costs. In related work, Kanatas and Qi (1998b) demonstrate that the incentive conflict of intermediaries who both lend and underwrite securities may impose a cost on their customers seeking to raise capital and that the regulatory separation of lending and underwriting may be optimal. They also find that when both the opportunity cost of the incentive conflict and the savings from economies of scope are sufficiently large, there is a (Onlinel Available rmJ/www.bog.frb.fed.us/qenerglinfo/sectionZOI, February 25, 1999. For a review of the consolidation of the financial services industry, see Berger et al 73 role for reputation building in mitigating the incentive conflict problem. This can be achieved without the need for regulation. Another possible mechanism commercial banks may use to enhance their credibility is the choice of an organizational form that distances the operations of lending and underwriting. Kroszner and Rajan (1997) study the underwriting activities of commercial banks before the Glass-Steagall Act. In the absence of other distortions, their results suggest that in comparison to the in-house department underwriting, the organizational structure of a separate affiliate is an effective commitment mechanism to address the conflicts of interest problem. They argue that market pressures force banks to adopt an internal structure that might mitigate these concerns. In a similar study by Gompers and Lerner (1998), the authors examine the underwriting of initial public offerings by investment banks that hold equity in a firm through a venture capital subsidiary. Consistent with the rational discounting hypothesis, investors require a greater discount at the time of the offering to compensate them for potential adverse selection. The investment bank-affiliated venture firms address the potential conflict of interest by investing in and subsequently underwriting less information-sensitive issues. Similar issues regarding the choice of organizational forms in dealing with different types of agency costs in the property-liability insurance industry are investigated by Cummins et al (1997). Their results support the hypothesis that the market will sort organizational forms into market segments where they have comparative advantages in minimizing the costs of production. By the same token, commercial banks may enter the security underwriting business by (1 999). 74 cooperating with a reputable investment bank to enlarge the distance between underwriting and lending when the concern for conflicts of interest perceived by the market is serious. Pichler and Wilhelm (1998) provide a model explaining the economic functions of the syndicate organizational form. This form provides a monitoring role for the lead undenrvriter that improves incentives and mitigates the moral hazard problem. It is through the delegation of additional powers and, thus, additional responsibilities that the lead banker is effectively forced to put at risk the reputational capital on which its future earnings power depends. Nanda and Yun (1997) find that lead managers share a larger proportion of the damage to reputation arising from an unsuccessful offering. Jain and Kini (1999) find evidence consistent with the demand for lead underwriter monitoring in initial public offerings (lPOs). The post-issue performance of IPO firms is positively associated with the lead bank reputation. In relation to our study, an investment bank without a conflict of interest problem is more credible in certifying a security issue when the purpose of the issue is to repay bank debt. It may pay for a commercial bank to participate in a syndicate as a co-manager and to allow a reputable investment bank to refinance the client's bank debt. By putting its reputation capital on the line, the lead investment bank may capture a larger share of the proceeds, and, thus, increase the probability of the bank leading future offerings or participating in syndicates that it does not lead. 75 The discussions in the previous paragraphs demonstrate that there are strong theoretical grounds for positive economic effects of commercial bank entry into the security underwriting business. There are two factors that may induce commercial banks to cooperate with investment banks in securities undenNritings. First, the aforementioned Federal Reserve revenue limitation hinders commercial banks from underwriting large issues. Second, investment banks have much more experience at these underwritings, putting commercial banks at a competitive disadvantage vis-a-vis investment banks. While the reasons for commercial banks to cooperate with investment banks are apparent, the reverse may not be so obvious. In the remainder of this section, we review the literature regarding the economic functions of syndicates and the possible reasons for coalitions among undenrvriters in the security underwriting business. Anand and Galetovic (1998) provide an explanation for oligopolistic behavior in the investment banking industry when property rights over information are weak. They study the effect of entry on equilibrium market structures and prices, and show that collusion is robust to information free riding and entry; in contrast, monopoly is not robust to either. When inputs are non-excludable, cooperation between firms may be necessary for the market to exist. The authors also derive ranges of the size and number of intermediaries in equilibrium. If intermediaries are too small, then incentives to free ride become too large. Conversely, intermediaries can not be too large, since they would reduce others' market shares to the point that cooperation would no longer be sustainable. This framework is applicable to entry of commercial banks into the security 76 underwriting market, since commercial banks can offer services similar to those of investment banks. Similar behavior of accommodating an entrant is observed in the discount department stores industry. Khanna and Tice (1998) study the expansion pattern of Wal-Mart, finding that the markets with high Herfindahl indices are the ones WaI-Mart can penetrate faster. These markets are dominated by large firms that tend to interact in multiple markets with Wal-Mart. Given this multi-market interaction, there is less of an information problem, and, thus, once entry takes place, incumbents are likely to cooperate with entrants. Bhattacharyya and Nanda (1998) discuss similar issues regarding cooperative arrangements among investment banks in the context of the introduction of innovative financial products. In their study, they show that an asymmetric distribution of market shares will tend to enhance innovation activity not only because the large bank has greater incentives to innovate but also because it is the natural partner for smaller banks in cooperative arrangements. In our paper, commercial banks are much smaller than investment banks in terms of market share. Alternatively, White (1996) argues that innovations can be organizational innovations involving new ways of doing things. In addition, Song (1999) find that commercial banks and investment banks possess differential comparative advantages in underwriting. Therefore, the formation of hybrid syndicates, which combine the complementary abilities of different undenrvriters, may provide a new breed of underwriting services. This new way of underwriting 77 would have never been available without the entry of commercial banks and the accommodation of investment banks. Mohanram and Nanda (1998) study the stock market reaction to joint venture announcements in an effort to identify which types of joint ventures create value. They find that the stock market reacts positively to joint ventures that pool complementary resources together. Analogous to our study, if the cooperative arrangement between commercial banks and investment banks is a valuable form of conducting security underwriting, the prices of bonds undenrvritten by this hybrid form should be higher than if the same clients had been underwritten by either a commercial bank lead syndicate or a pure investment bank syndicate. Although the cooperation between commercial banks and investment banks could have existed before the Glass-Steagall Act, we are not aware of any study that investigates this interesting issue during the pre- Glass—Steagall era. 78 2.3 Data and Summary Statistics The sample consists of 1327 public debt offerings45 between January 1, 1991 and December 31, 1996. Data after 1996 is not included due to the increase in the revenue limitation imposed on commercial bank underwriting activities”. Financial companies and utilities are excluded from the sample. Characteristics of the issues are obtained from the Security Data Corporation (SDC) U.S. Debt New Issues Database, while firm characteristics are drawn from Compustat and CRSP. In order to be included in our analysis, an issuing firm must have data available on SDC, CRSP and Compustat. Definitions of variables used in the analysis are listed in Appendix A. The frequency and percentage of bond issues by year and underwriter types during the period 1991 to 1996 are reported in Table 2.1, Panels A and B, respectively. Over the six-year period, commercial banks lead managed 184 bond issues. Of the issues led by commercial banks, 155 issues did not have other commercial banks involved as co-managers. These commercial bank lead issues (commercial bank-lead syndicates) may or may not have had investment banks involved. Twenty-nine issues did have other commercial banks involved as co-managers (commercial bank-coop syndicates). There are no observations of commercial bank-coop syndicates in our sample for 1991, 1992 or 1994. Ideally, ‘5 Equity issues are not included in the sample due to an insufficient number of observations of commercial bank lead underwritings. ‘6 The revenue limitation was raised from 10 percent to 25 percent at the end of 1996. See Federal Reserve System Docket No. R-0841, "Revenue Limit on Bank-Ineligible Activities of Subsidiaries of Bank Holding Companies Engaged in Underwriting and Dealing in Securities.” 79 we would like to analyze the commercial bank-coop category separately, but the number of issues is too few for multivariate analysis. Thus, in this section, we analyze these 29 issues as an independent category, but when we conduct the multivariate analysis in next section, these issues are lumped in with other commercial bank-lead-managed issues. In the next section we relabel this new category as CB-Lead syndicate. Additionally, there are 345 issues underwritten by the hybrid syndicate form. The hybrid form is the syndicate organizational form where an investment bank is the lead manager while a commercial bank is a co-manager. Finally, 798 issues are undertaken by pure investment bank syndicates (PurelB). Over the sample period, the hybrid syndicate form has increased dramatically from underwriting 9.8 percent of bond issues in 1991 to 37.7 percent in 1996. This increase is at the expense of pure investment bank syndicates, who underwrote 86 percent of bond issues in 1991, but only 43.6 percent in 1996. Although the number of commercial bank-lead managed issues increased over the sample period regardless of whether other commercial banks were involved as co-managers, the percent of the total issues in the sample is relatively small. In fact, commercial bank-lead issues as a percent of total issues actually decreased in 1996. The results indicate that commercial banks enter the market under two possible forms - as lead underwriters, or as co-managers. The latter form occurred twice as often as the former did. Thus, it appears that investment banks choose to accommodate entry rather than to deter it. One interesting question is 80 if a commercial bank is just another investment bank. Therefore, the observed accommodation of entry is the process of a natural oligopolistic market structure. Or there are special characteristics of commercial banks that cause them to stay competitive as lead undenrvriters when they possess advantages over investment banks and to ally themselves with investment banks as co-managers when they have weakness in certain markets. The descriptive statistics reported in Table 2.2 demonstrate that commercial bank-lead syndicates underwrite the smallest issues in terms of the mean and median of issue size. Conversely, hybrid syndicates underwrite the largest issues. There is no observable difference of issue size between pure investment bank syndicates and commercial bank-coop syndicates. We do not observe the same pattern among different syndicates in terms of issuing firm size. Pure investment bank syndicates underwrite the largest mean and median size firms, while commercial bank-coops underwrite the smallest firms. Both commercial bank-lead and hybrid syndicates underwrite for middle size firms. The former underwrites relatively smaller firms than the latter on average, but there is no difference in median statistics. Thus, although hybrid syndicates underwrite the largest issue size, they do not serve the largest clients. In fact, pure investment bank syndicates serve the largest client firms. The smallest client firms are assisted by commercial bank-coops but their issue sizes are significantly larger than the issue sizes of the commercial bank-lead clients. The net yields, or basis points spread (BPS), of bond issues highlight another pattern. While the bond issues of commercial bank-lead clients have the 81 lowest BPS, those of commercial bank-coops have the highest BPS. Although the BPS of commercial bank-coop underwritten issues is significantly higher than that of commercial bank-lead underwritten issues, it is not significantly different from those of hybrid or pure investment bank underwritten issues. The latter two syndicate forms do not differ from each other in terms of mean and median of BPS, but the BPS of their client bond issues are both significantly larger than that of commercial bank-lead syndicates. Due to the limited nature of univariate analysis, we will analyze the interesting patterns observed in this section further via multivariate analysis in Section 2.5. 82 2.4 The Entry Strategies of Commercial Banks In this section, we continue our univariate analysis to identify systematic differences between syndicate forms. We then proceed to multivariate analysis in the next section. Table 2.3 displays the distributions of issue credit ratings by different types of syndicates. Regardless of the pairs we compare, all of the distributions are significantly different from each other. In the high quality segment, where the Moody's credit ratings are either Aaa or Aa, the dominant players are the hybrid and pure investment bank syndicates. The BPS of bond issues do not differ between these two syndicates nor among all syndicate types. The commercial bank-lead syndicates only underwrite 14 out of 187 (7.5%) high quality issues, indicating that they can not penetrate this particular market very well as a lead underwriter. There are 46 out of 187 (24.6%) high quality issues in which commercial banks participate as co-managers, which is slightly lower than for the overall sample (26%) when the market is not segmented by credit ratings. No issues in this segment are underwritten by commercial bank-coop syndicates. In the middle quality category, where the Moody's credit ratings are either A or Baa, commercial bank-lead syndicates are able to lower BPS significantly more for their clients than hybrid or pure investment bank syndicates are able to. Commercial bank-lead syndicates underwrite 13.4% of these issues. This percentage is almost double that of the high quality firm segment. In fact, if we add the issues underwritten by commercial bank-coops, the number more than doubles. Among all the commercial bank-lead underwritten issues, 77.5 percent 83 of them are middle-rated firms, while for the hybrid underwritten issues and pure investment bank underwritten issues, the percentages are 62.4 and 67.9, respectively. For those with B credit ratings, hybrid syndicates and commercial bank-coop syndicates show a comparative advantage over commercial bank-lead and pure investment bank syndicates in lowering BPS for their clients. In these low quality segments, i.e. Ba and below, the percentages of issues underwritten by hybrid and commercial bank-coop syndicates are 34 and 5.26, respectively. The percentage of issues underwritten by commercial bank-coops in the middle-rated category (1.79%), is one third that of the non-investment grade category. Conversely, hybrid syndicates underwrite 10 percent more issues in the non- investment grade segment than in the investment grade category. The figures in Table 2.3 demonstrate a pattern of systematic selection of different syndicates by client firms. Investment banks continue to be the dominant players in the high quality segment. Commercial banks appear to be able to penetrate this market by cooperating with a lead investment bank. Commercial banks also lead-manage a larger proportion of the middle quality segment, where they show a comparative advantage in lowering the net yield of their clients' bond issues. In the non-investment grade market, where commercial bank-lead syndicates do not show a distinct advantage, cooperative arrangements with either investment banks or another commercial bank are the dominant strategies of entry for commercial banks. The specializations and different forms of entry by commercial banks indicate that a commercial bank is 84 not another "pure investment bank". If there were no difference between commercial banks and investment banks, we should not observe these systematic patterns of entry and selection. In Table 2.4, we show the percentages of bonds underwritten by different types of syndicates in the small and large issue markets. These markets are segmented by the median size of issues of the entire sample. Thus, the small issue market contains issues that are less than 150 million dollars, while the large issue market has issues that are greater than or equal to 150 million dollars. In the small issue market, the percentage of commercial bank lead- managed bond issues is 18.6 percent on average, which is more than triple that of bond issues lead-managed by commercial banks in the large issue market. Conversely, the percentage of hybrid managed bond issues is on average 17.6 percent in the small issue market, while the percentage doubles for the large issue market. The above pattern of entry into different issue size markets selected by commercial banks is consistent with the findings in Song (1999) that commercial banks show a disadvantage in handling large issues. If we combine the percentage of bond issues of hybrid syndicates and commercial bank lead syndicates, we find that commercial banks are actively engaging in the large issue market, but mainly by cooperating with an investment bank that may have a better distributional network and is not restricted by the 10 percent revenue limitation imposed on commercial banks. 85 Effective on November 12, 1996, commercial banks are allowed to exclude the interest earned on the ineligible securities from the 10 percent revenue limit". This amendment would decrease the quarterly ineligible revenue of some section 20 subsidiaries by a magnitude ranging between 19 percent and 79 percent. Since revenue limitations are calculated over a rolling eight-quarter period, commercial banks that anticipated this change may increase their underwritings in 1996. As shown in Table 2.4, there is a shift of underwriting activities by commercial banks from the small to the large issue market. Issues managed by CB-Lead and hybrid syndicates in the small issue market declined dramatically in percentage terms from 1995 to 1996, while the opposite occurred in the large issue market. Although the overall mean and median of the issue size of hybrid syndicate underwritten bonds are significantly larger than for any other form of syndicate, the firm size of hybrid syndicate clients is significantly smaller than that of pure investment bank syndicates in both mean and median. Compared to commercial bank lead syndicates, the firm size of hybrid syndicate clients is larger for means but no different for medians. However, examining the results of probit regression in Table 2.5, which analyze the pairwise syndicate selection, we find hybrid clients are significantly larger in firm size and in issue size than CB-Lead clients, but there is no difference between hybrid clients and PurelB clients in these two variables. ‘7 See Federal Register, September 17, 1996, "10 Percent Revenue Limit on Bank- lneligible Activities of Subsidiaries of Bank Holding Companies Engaged in Underwriting and Dealing in Securities," volume 61(181):48953—48954. 86 Tables 2.6 and 2.7 report the results of net yields (BPS) regressions that demonstrate the undenrvriting ability of syndicates. we compare the beta coefficients of firm size, proxied by log of market value of equity. The coefficient estimate of firm size for hybrid syndicates is -27.32, which is smaller than that of PurelB syndicates in Table 2.7, but considerably larger than the CB-Lead estimate in Table 2.6. Thus, hybrid syndicates do not maintain the advantage that CB—Lead syndicates have shown in assisting large firms in lowering their net yields of bond issues. This may explain why hybrid syndicates do not underwrite for the largest firms even though its clients have the largest issue size. In summary, the results support the hypothesis that the entry modes of commercial banks are strategically chosen. In the segment of middle quality firms where commercial bank show better ability, they behave more aggressively to acquire the lead-manager role. In the large issue market, where they are unable to handle large issues due to existing regulations, commercial banks tend to cooperate with investment banks. 87 2.5 The Characteristics of Hybrid Syndicates The specialization of different syndicates mentioned in the previous sections implies that underwriting abilities are different amongst the various syndicates. In this section, we examine how these abilities are different based on firm and issue characteristics and how the differences affect client firms. Due to the multiple choices of syndicates and a potential endogenous selection problem, polychotomous choice selectivity model would be the preferred choice of model. However, parameter estimates in this model are very sensitive to distributional assumptions“. Because of this lack of robustness in polychotomous choice selectivity models, we apply a framework of switching regression analysis with endogenous switching that involves analysis of two choices. We use pairwise comparisons of different syndicates in the first-stage probit analysis. Thus, we have three pairs of syndicates - CB-Lead versus Hybrid, CB-Lead versus PurelB, and Hybrid versus PureIB - we need to consider. In the second stage, we estimate the bond pricing equations, that is the net yield or BPS equations, for each type of syndicate using an endogenous selection adjustment term estimated from the first-stage probit”. ‘8 Chung (1997) applies polychotomous choice selectivity models, which allow for different distributional assumptions, to male wages in four sectors. The multiple selections of sectors are controlled for when the male wage equations are estimated. The results are quite different for different models and estimation methods. ‘9 See Maddala (1983) for detailed discussions of both the switching regression with endogenous switching model and the two-stage estimation method, and Song et al (1999) for an application in the underwriter selection problem and discussions of variables used in the analysis. 88 2. 5.1 The Determinants of Syndicate Selections We analyze the selection of syndicates by probit models, presenting coefficient estimates in Table 2.5. We focus on the differences in selecting CB- Lead versus Hybrid and Hybrid versus PurelB syndicates, attempting to identify if the characteristics of hybrid syndicate clients are similar to CB-Lead, PurelB, or neither. The overall results indicate that these three types of syndicates are different from each other and that the hybrid syndicate is not the simple average of a commercial bank lead syndicate and a pure investment bank syndicate. Hybrid syndicates are similar to commercial bank lead syndicates in terms of leverage, past 5-year sales growth, operating income, and cash reserves. Both syndicates are associated with firms that have lower leverage, grow slower, have higher operating income and higher cash reserves. All of the estimates of these variables are not significant for the CB-Lead vs. Hybrid regression, but they are all significant for the Hybrid vs. PureIB regression. Hybrid syndicates resemble pure investment bank syndicates on the dimensions of equity trading volume, Tobin's q, firm size, issue size, and the interaction between high interest expense and the purpose of issue repaying bank debt. In comparison to CB-Lead clients, hybrid clients tend to have lower Tobin's q, to be larger firms, to be traded more frequently in the equity markets. Their clients also tend to issue bonds with larger size and fewer bonds with high interest expense for the purpose of refinancing bank debt than CB-Lead clients do. 89 A hybrid syndicate resembles neither a commercial bank lead syndicate nor a pure investment bank syndicate when maturity of issue, the purpose of issue and credit ratings are considered. These three syndicates are not significantly different in volatility of stock return, interest expense relative to operating income and reduction in long-term debt. Based on the above results, we may characterize the clients of hybrid syndicates as firms with better quality, having higher profitability and cash reserves, lower leverage, and less of an informational problem, having lower Tobin's q, higher equity trading volume and larger firm size. They issue bonds of significantly larger size compared to issues underwritten by commercial bank lead syndicates. Hybrid syndicates' clients are more likely to issue debt to refinance existing bank debt with lower interest expense relative to operating income. Hybrid syndicate issues have longer maturity and they have a higher tendency to be non-investment grade. The distinct characteristics of hybrid clients sheds some light on the possible economic rationales of cooperation between commercial banks and investment banks, and yielding an understanding of the role of commercial banks as co-managers in the security underwriting business. Given the aforementioned evidence on systematic selection of hybrid syndicates, a more thorough analysis of comparative advantages of hybrid syndicates over other forms is warranted. Therefore, we estimate the bond pricing, or BPS equations for different syndicates, analyzing their comparative advantages in the following subsection. 90 2. 5.2 The Underwriting Abilities of Syndicates We investigate the underwriting abilities of syndicates by estimating bond pricing equations in Tables 2.6 and 2.7. Regression results of the BPS equations for different syndicates are reported. Since we use net yields as the dependent variable in the BPS equation, the larger the beta coefficients, the lower the bond prices the syndicates can achieve for their clients. In Table 2.6, we report two BPS regressions of CB-Lead syndicates with different endogenous selection adjustment terms, one estimated from the pair comparison of CB-Lead vs. PurelB (CB-Lead (1 )), and the other from that of CB- Lead vs. Hybrid (CB-Lead (2)). The third set of regression results in Table 2.6 is for hybrid syndicates. Since there is no evidence of selection bias, we report only the estimates without the control of endogenous selection. For completeness, additional BPS regressions for hybrid syndicates with the control of selection bias are presented in Appendix B4. In Table 2.7, the estimates of all three possible regression specifications are presented for the PurelB syndicates. We first examine if hybrid syndicates preserve the advantages of commercial banks. The proxy variables used in studying the informational and relationship-oriented advantages of commercial banks with their clients are leverage (total debt/total asset), equity trading volume, volatility of equity return, Tobin's q and an endogenous selection adjustment term. The estimate of leverage for hybrid clients is very similar to that for commercial bank lead clients, with both being negative and statistically insignificantly. This results indicate that 91 hybrid syndicate preserves the advantage of a commercial bank on the dimension of leverage. Conversely, the estimate for pure investment bank clients is positive and statistically significant. Based on the equity trading volume variable in Table 2.6, hybrid syndicates obtain bond prices for their clients that are very close to the simple averages of CB-Lead and PurelB syndicates. As for the estimates of volatility of equity return and Tobin's q, hybrid syndicates can do better than the other two types of syndicates. The estimates of these two variables for hybrid syndicate are the smallest among all types of syndicates. The estimates of the endogenous selection adjustment terms for commercial bank lead syndicates are both negative and statistically significant regardless of the pair comparisons. When compared to CB-Lead syndicates, these estimates for both hybrid and PureIB syndicates are not statistically significant. One way to interpret the adjustment term of endogenous selection is as a proxy of private information extracted from the identity of syndicates. The negative estimates of CB-Lead syndicates50 indicate that they can lower the net yields of their clients' bond issues further even though all other exogenous characteristics of firms have been controlled for. Thus, commercial banks can cherry-pick the clients they can serve better based on endogenous selection. ¢(Zr) I — 00000. 0000 .0 6000005 00... .< .0000 000.0 0050200000 05 .0 000 .0 .000008 -00 0 00 0029:. 00.000 .0.0.08800 .050 000 00.0.5 000 .000 0.208800 0 0. .0.0200000 000. 05 00.0.5 0. 00.00.00? 08000.00. 0000-02.00 0.808800 0.000 808.008. 00 0. 0.03.0000 000. 05 000 0029:. 00.000 .0.0.08800 00 0.0 0.05 00.55 0. 0.00.050 0. 0.000 808.008.. 0.01 .0000. 00 0. 00208. 0.0 00.000 .0.0.08800 .050 000 .0.0200000 000. 05 00 0.000 808.002.. 00 0>00 00.03 0900.050 08000.00. 0.000.. .0000. 05 0. 00208. 0. x000 .0.0.08800 .050 00 .00 0.080000 000. 05 00 0.000 .0.0.08800 0 0.00 00.02, 0080.050 000000.00. 0003.000 50.08800 .003 .0.0200000 >0 000 .00.» >0 5.0500000. .0 000 < .0000 0. 000000. 0.0 00000. 0000 .0 000080800 000 0.00800 .000... 00.: .00....30000 .3 000 .00» >0 00000. 0000 no 005000.00 000 600000.: 00... fin 0.00... 102 00.. NN v.00 0.0N N: ommviwmmv 00.. 0.0 0.00 5.50 0.N_. 000w 00.. 0.0 0.0.0 5N0 0.0? 000—. Dov 0.0 0.00 v.00 0.0.. 30—. Dow w.—. v.00 0.0m 0.0? 000.. 00.. 0.0 0.00 v._.N 9.0—. Nmmw cow 0.0 0.00 0.0 N0 900—. 0000 0.000 000.. 0003...? 0.000 30.08800 «0080002.. 0.00 000.... 0.000 30.08800 .00> 00000. 0000 .0 00.900030 0:... .m .0000 .350. 3. 0.0a» 103 .8 00.0 00.0 5.0 . 00.0 . . 8.8.0200 00.328 2 00. z 0 F .0? 3.0 0.0.2 om. : R? 20, €00 0:05.095 050 m 0.0 R? 00.0 N: 3.0 0: 00.: 25>: 00.0 00.0 8.0 00.0 00.0 02: 5.0 82-022 00.05500 A0250 8 0902:0003 >0 0N5 FEE .5300. 000—2 802 9: o: . on? 0. . 8-8-0.ch 00.05.80 3 of 2: 03 2: on. 02 a? 0.53 20.5095 050 “0: com of o2 o: 80 SN 25>: V0 2: 0? 2 2: 2: 8. 820.50 00.05500 A0057: 3 00:02:00.0: >0 0N5 0000. 0050—2 803 at 02 . om. . . 8.8.0000 00.0558 2 0: 03 02 02 02 SN 000 0.53 202095 050 ~80 000 new com «5 0.0 80 25>: mm .5 S 00 00 5 3: 000.022 00.08500 ACE—=5 $0 00:02:09.3 >0 0N5 0300. .505. 002-32 002 008 32 88 $2 32 30> 2:208 0.0000800 00 E5000 03000.... .00 00 22> 080 x0 05 .05 0:00 0 00 000.00 0_0_> 080 x0 05 00 8280.0 05 0_ 000.00 0.500 0000 00... 00.60 00050 E 0500 00 30> 000008 000 0_ 08:0 00 000 00k .000 00088000: >0 0:0 00> >0 000000. 0.0 00:00_ 0:00 00 0000.00 .500 0000 000 0000 000. 00>“ 00:02:00,... >0 0:0 00> >0 0000000000000 8.5 0:0 0:00_ 0:00 00 0000080 020000000 «.0. 0.00... 104 .aooo-xcmm 36.08500 new 255 Emgmgs 05m c0928 2:69: :o :59: S 855:6 EmoEcgm . .Eooo-xcmm _m_o:mEEoov 253 80869:. 2.5 new 25>: cmmzamn 3:69: :0 game 5 macemtfi E8535 :3: .Eooo-xcmm $688500 .xcmm E9535. 22:: 25>: new 832 832:8 38.58800 5923 3:69: :o 2:08 :_ moan-5:6 EmoEcgw GEM u :: :2 v: - a: - - 8-82:2 358558 a .8 :: m: :N 8 N2 :2 2:2 88:25 :5: a :: m: :5 8 N: 5 v: 25»... N: :: :: F: 2 :: :: 822:2 322.58 >n cmttEmucD mmawfl .9 Omaha—w “Eon m_mmm agnos— u :9 :2 :3 - F2 - . 8-82:2 68.2.58 3 :2 2: :9 :2 SP :8 E 2:2 E2825 :5: a :2 our 8. x: NE E :3 :22: E 2. :: :3 v: a: N: 822:2 522.58 >0 :mEScmocD m03m£ .0:— Ummaw “Eon m_wmm cam—2 :8 2.: 8w ::.: - Se - . 8-82:2 86.2.58 3 ::.v 8.: :5: F: 8.: _ 8.: 2.: 2:2 22.88:. as: 2.: 2.: 2.: 2.: EN vim 2.: 88: 8.: 5.: :3 :3 8.: 3.: :3 822:2 36.2.58 ”32:3 3 $5253: >9 mum ctr. 53mm. 52005. $2.32 :8. :8. 32 22 82 32 28> 5.80. Na :32 105 2:00 808::08. :0: m. .2000 .0.0:08800 :0: :0:0:: mo .080: 05 0:0 ::0:.:>>:00c: £00 >0 00088000: :0:::_ :0: 80.30086 :0::0: :.00:0 05 :05 00.00 :_:0£00>:_ =2: 05 5.3 .:0:0£c0:00 c. 03.0>-0 0:0 ::0: 0:000:80 0:: :50800 0.00: 0:: c. :30: 00:5 ::0_ 0E- .>.0>.:000:0: .:0:::. 000020000: 0000-0800 .0.0:08800 0:0 2:00 808::08. 0:00 :0: :0::08 080: 05 c. 005:00 0:0 2:80.00 008.080: 0;... .:0:::. 000020000: 0.:0>.. :0: m 000 .N .F :08200 c. :05 :0 00:08:08. 080: 05 3.0800 0 000 .m .0 9:83.00 .:0:::_ 000020000: 000.2800 .0.0:08800 05 :0: 300200 9:00: :.00:0 2000 :0: mmm. :0 00608 000 :c008 0;: >0 00326: 500060 9:00: :.00:0 0000 :0: 0.080: 0...: :0 0060090 05 8.0800 083.00 :2: 0:.» 30308 03200800 :0 >830: 33:00:... .m.: :0 0_0_> 080 x0 0;: :0>0 0:00 0 :0 000:0: 0.0_> 080 x0 05 :0 82.890 05 :_ 0.0-0m. 000:0: :860 :_:00 0:: 00>: 3:03.600: >0 0009.0: 8.00 :.000 0:0 00300506 09:00.: :.00:0 .8300. nN 0.00... 106 20000-2000 .0.0:08800. 2000 808808. 0:30 000 0.:0>... 0002000 :00608 :0 :0008 0. 0000:0::6 8000.005 0: 20000-2000 .0.0:08800 .2000 808808. 0:30. 0.:0>I 000 :03::. 0003-2000 .0.0:08800 0002003 :00608 :0 :0008 0. 00090.20 8000.006 .83 :0000 00:0:000 :003.00. 8000.00 :.0... : 80.0: 00.00 80.0. 3.3 .000. 9.0m 0009mm: .:> .30. 00:: 82:: :0:: 0.8:: .:> .80. 8.8 22>: .:> 20.0.00 .. .. 0.0 mmm mmm 0.0 00.: 000 0.0 2 .. 0.0 «30.00 :0 o u 000 n 000 0.0: :09. 8000 0.: a 000 a 000 00.. ~00 mm: 0.: m 0:0 «mm 0. :0 8000 803 0.0 mmm 3w 0.0: «K 00w 0.: 0m s 00 8 K. 0:0 85: 803 Yam :0 00: Now N0 00 0.8 00m :0 v: NC 80> 800 0N0 : >0 2 Nu >00 mm 00 0.00 < .. 2 0.0 00 0: m.) :0 mm 0.0: mm mm 0.0 0< .. .. 0.0 :0 >0 0.: 00 00 0d . .. 0.0 00< 0060.2 000.2 0060.2 000.2 0060.2 000.2 0060.2 000.2 000000 000:0w 03::. 000:0w 03::. 000:0w 03::. 000:0w 03::. :.00:0 8.00 :.:00 :0 .2: 8.00 :.:00 :0 .x. 8.00 2:00 :0 :8 8.00 :.:00 :0 .x: 0.600: 00002.00m .0.0:08800 200m «005008. 0:30 23>... 0032.00m .0.0:08800 QN 030... 107 OOF 7N mdm m.mm oh mam—3.60.. co.- o.m NNN odm md mom.- oow 7m mdm va 6v mmmw co.- od mdm 0.5m 0d V09. 00.- vé 5.00 Pdm Q? Maw—- 00.. Cd v.00 NdN vb NmmP cow 0.0 mém 0N.- Nd ram—- 0000 200m 000.. 000>...-..< -2000 .0.0:08800 808.008. 0:30 0.:0>... .200m .0.0:08800 :00> .0808 0300. 0.01:0. 05 0. 00300. 0000 :0 $0809.00 00... .< .0000 030:0 0000200003 00. :0 000 :0 :000008 -00 0 :0 00208. 02000 .0.0:08800 :080 :00 00.03 000 2000 .0.0:08800 0 :. :0880003 000. 00. 00.03 0. :0.00.00>: 080:0:00: 0000-2000 .0.0:08800 .2000 808.008. 00 :. :0880003 000. 00. 000 00208. 02000 .0.0:08800 00 0:0 0:00. 00.02, 0. 0.0060>: :. 2000 8002008. 0:30 .0300. 00 0. 00208. 0:0 02000 .0.0:08800 :050 000 :0880003 000. 00. :0 2000 808.008. 00 08... 00.03 00.00.00? 0.000080: 0.002.. .0300. 00. 0. 00208. 0. 2000 .0.0:08800 :050 00 .30 :0880003 000. 00. :0 2000 .0.0:08800 0 080 00.02, :0:00.00>: :.00:0:00: 000.2000 .0.0:08800 .0.080: 0:.80 0.... :0 030:. :0 00.: $8.60 00....8 0:: 00608 00: >0 0080800: 0. 00.: 030:. 00:. 2028030: 0:02:08 03:0. :08: 000 03:0. 00:0. 00. :0: m 000 < .0000 0. 000000: 0:0 00220880003 >0 0030:. 0000 :0 000080200 0....- 80800: 0300. :08: 000 0300. 00:0. 00: 0. 003230200003 >0 00300. 0000 :0 00080200 02... 0.0 0.00h 108 00: «.0 o. :0 0.0: 0.0: 000750: 00: 0.0 ~00 :.:: N0: 000: 00: N0 0.00 0.00 0.00 000: 00: 0.0 0.00 :.00 0.0: 000: 00: 0.0 0.00 0.0: 0.0: 000: 00: 0.0 :.:: :.:: 8:: ~00: 00: 0.0 0.00 0.0 00 :00: 0000 0.00m 000.. 000>:.-..< -200m .0.0:08800 0000:0008. 0:30 0.:0>... 0.00m .0.0:08800 :00> 00000.0 0300. =0E0 05 0. 00300. 0000 :0 000000200 00... .m .0000 .0800. 0.0 200: 109 0003.00. 0:0 >00. 00300. 000000: .00 0:0 08:0. 80.0000 000 00.8830 800.. 00. :0: 00.08.00 00... .08000. 00000000 0. 02.0.0: 000090 .0008. 000 .000 2000 00000000 :0 8:0. 00:00:08. 00. 0. 0000020 .00:08...000 2000 00000000 .0.00.:0> 0.0. :0 00.008 00. 000. 00:0. 0. 08000. 0000000 0. 02.0.0: 000090 .0008. :0 _0>0_ 00. :. : 0. 03.0> 0000.000 00. .0_00.:0> >8830 0 0. 5.00.00. .0008. 00.: 00.20008 0 ..000 2000 000000 0000000: 0. 0. 03:0. :0 0:00:30 00. :. : 0. .00. 0.00.:0> >8830 0 0. .000 2000 00000000 .0.0:00 _0.0. >0 000.20 3.300 :0 03.0> .02:08 03.0 .000 :0 03.0> 2000 00. >0 000000 0. 0 0.0.00 :. 00.20006 0 00.0: .00 :0 2.200 :0 00 0. 03:0. 0000 00. :0: 08.0: .000 0.8005. 00. :. : 0. 000:0 808.008.-002 000:0 808.008.-000 0. .. :. .m 0. 03_0> 00. .000 :0 < 0. .. :. _N 0. 03.0> 00. .0< :0 00< 0. 0300. 0000 00. :0: 0000: :.00:0 0.8005. 00. :. : 0. 00:0: ..00:0 00208. 0:0 02000 808.008. 200 .00. 0.00.00>0 00. :0: 0000.: 0.050 >02. 0800 00. 0. 000000 0:0 0083.00 008.080: 00. .0000... .02000 .0.0:08800 0..2. 00.0:00000 .. 000 2000 808.008. 00 0. 08200003 002 05 0. .00. .052 m 0. ._ :_ o 0:0 .253 00:00:58 0 0. 0.0808: 000 00. :_ : :_ €03-00. 030:9, .5880: 00. .: 083.00 0. 00000300 0000200 0.0200003 :0 .00.-. :0 :03_0>-0 000 00.08000 000:0 00.20.00 00. 00000: 0.00.0.0... 000000.00 0.00.00>0 :0 8000.80.00 00. :0 00:00:..0m m.~ 0.00... 110 00.. 000 000 08000008 .0 .oz 00... 0.0 3.0 8.8800 .00 .80- 0.0 08.0- 0.0 08.0- 500 5.0.002 0. 02.8000 00.0 80.0 8.0 08.0 00.0 .80 Emma-.0000 0.2.2000 .00 05.0 0.0 002.0- .00 .200- 000:0 005.095-82 00.0 000.0 8.0 000.0 3.0 30.0 05.0: .090 5.8.00. 00.0 .02.- 00.0 3.0 00.0 00.0 .090... .0: - .00.. .00.. 8000000 :0 000.0- 3.0 08.0- R... 0.0.0 00:80. 0009002000006 .0900. .0.00.:0> 8.0 000.0 .00 000.0- 8.0 0.0.0- 0.800.. .00.. .03 8000000 .00 08.0- 8.0 000.0- 8.0 00.0- .0300. :0 000.03 00.0 0.0.0 «0.0 0.....- No.0 «0.0. .0500 :o 020:, 0005.03 8.0 0.0.0 .0... 2.0.0 0.0 .000- 0.0000 0.020580. 05.2000 00.0 0.0.... 8.0 at... 0...: 00.0 0 0.050. 8.0 .80- 2.0 30.0- .00 30.0 .0>-0. 526:0 0200 00.0 08.0 .00 0.0.0- 80 Rod- 0:00. :0 0.5.0.2 00.0 .000- 000 .000- 00.0 0.0.0- 0030.09. 0:30: 0.300 :0 0___.0_o> 00.0 .80 00.0 30.0- .00 08.0- 0.022, 00.00:. 0500 No.0 .80- 8.0 0.0.0- 00.0 08.0- 0.0000 0.02.000 _0.0. 03.0>-n. m.mE_.mw 03.0>-n. m.mE_.mm 03.0>-n. 908....wm mm_nm_:m> .chchmOE .. n 0000.. .. H 83.00. .. u 0003-00. 03009 00000000 0.0.30 .0> 0002.. 0050 .0> 083.00 0.5.: .0> 003-00 0." 030... 111 .3385 En >9: 2955 nmtoam. 6: 2m 9.53 Emwmcoo ncm mm_EE:n >=mm> m5 .8 8.9233 ms... .mEooE 9:5an 2 @252 mmcmaxm 6295 new Emu xcmn 8:2ch *0 gm: 8:09.35 2: 2 $598 $922.28 xcmn wocmccmm .mmsamfio o .Emu xcmo 95:8 @2856. 2 w_ 952 B 8092. 9: t F 2 “m5 033.? 2:88 m m_ Emu xcmo mocmccmm 23$ .82 >2 822v 353 n.0 m:_m> 5me man Emu ho m:_m> xoon m5 3 nmccmn m_ a 3.50» .mmEcmcE o .83. 8: 5 26.09 5 mm m_ 03$ neon m5 .8 95m. :85 @3022 9: t F m_ mama EmEummETcoz .mnma EmEummETco: m_ g .._ .m m_ m2m> 9: .95 .o < 2 g a .N m_ m:_m> m5 .m< .o mm< w_ mzmfl neon m5 .2 mczm. :88 {6002 m5 2 F w_ 95m. .690 SE“ EmEfiivm mzocmmoncm 25.05 8: $8 56859 9: van mmzmg cmESCmncsfitgc 9: 2:0 $3.05 29:3 9: .0 new m 9.828 :. .mmfiofiiw 25>: .w> nmm..-mo 3 “m5 933 Amy tam..-mo .3522? 92:; .m> umm._-mo “6 28:32.8 :3 m5 3% A: ummfifio .coszzmm 305 39ng 9: E0: $65.30 9m mmmmfi cozoflmm maocmmoccm m5 .058 2 8m: £59 EmEuwzfim msocmmoucm .6mm..-mov 6:352: 93. 9: m_ xcmn _m_8mEEoo a 5:2, $33 .8385 99:3 05 .v 2 P 2.5.8 5 .69; B mm:_m>-a 98 255.852 Ammmv mummaw Eon $me 3299.83 ho £58508 38 m5 roam. o 2 F 28200 6335:?» 25>... can two..-mo 3 205.3332: £23: :0 acacia “Eon mine no 3353mm m.~ min... 112 113 mvm X: X: 225388 3 .oz mud mmd mmd mm 853.6(- - - mod 8.8- 86 3.2- :5. 23.8.8 88385 23 m P .9: cod 8n: 2:. 3.8. 2.95 55395.82 mmcmaxm Ed 3.2 5.0 8.0a No.0 3. z: 3925 - 5% was 8cmémm 8d 8.3 So 3.: mod 3.8 9:85 839805283 399:. Ami—25> and 2.8- ood 2.3- So BB- 58.2: 5% EB Beacemm 2d 8.0 8.0 o; So m3 833 ho 3353 8d «QR- 8d 5.2..- go 8.8- $58 ho was, 552.53 Nod R. F- 8.0 So. Ed who 33$ @2385 9:230 mad m3 and 52 93 mom a 3.38 $6 9.0 cod o: cod Rd 33.8 €85 83w 8d «3 2.0 m3- and and 2.3 3 £552 8d SN cod ~20- ood 8m $353: 539 35am .6 a___§o> So 2d 2.0 was. omd emo- meae, 9.6m: :55 :.o and. 86 3o- mud 3.? 93% _Sosgmu EB m:_m>-n_ QmEzmw mam-Si mumEzmw mews-n. 295mm mofimtm> Emncmamns 23;: Q 83.8 E 83-8 QN «En-_- .8365 9m >9: canon. nmtoam. .9. 9a 959 E938 new $3.83 >_.mm> m5 .0. 999.33 05 .coszzwm .305 mom-am -6... 9: E9. 888:8 9m 9..me c2823 msocmmoucm 9: 62:8 2 8m: £59 EmEfiafim mzocmmoncm .0885 9599.0 o. @269 $598 699... new 59. xcmn mocmccmm .o 8.9 820995 on. w. mmcmaxm $995.53 xcmo mocmccmm .mm_2cm£o o .59. xcmn 9.32.8 8559 o. m_ 95m. .6 309:5 9: t F m. 65 033.9 >EEzn m m_ 500 xcmn mocmccmm .233 92 .5 8220 353 .o m2m> .352. men Emu .o m:_m> x89 9: >3 3:ch m_ a 3.58 .mm_>>.m£o o .399 .0: .o .529. .0 mm m_ 96m. 9.09 9: .2 959 .690 $6022 9: ._ F m_ 9.90 EmE.mm>c_-coz .muma EmE.mm>:_ .5: m. z t .m m. m:_m> 9.. 6%. .o < a g t .N m_ m2m> 93 dd. .0 mm< m_ mamfl 9.02 9: .o. 9.39 .690 3600.2 9.: t F m_ 9.29 .690 .E.9 EmEfiafim mnocmmoncm 9: 9.205 .0: $8 8. 99:... .wmfiofigm m_9:a .m> 25>: .6 65 8mg AN. 99.5 .8522? 99am .m> FEB-mo .o 52.9.2.8 ._ma 9: $3 E 993.. .coszzmm .505 mafia-.9: 9: So... 8662mm 9m 835 5.623 msocmmoocm 9.. 6.2.8 9 8m: 2:9 E9536... maocmmovcw .69... .0 mm:_m>-a new 986:? m_9:n_ .0 9.23909 Ammmv 959% .58 mama mama-0:83 .0 9:20:38 99. 05 team. 0 o. F 9.8200 .3352?» 993.. .5 53:33:: 3:2. :0 «39% «Son «Ban .0 3qusz EN snub 114 m2 m9. 8. 253298 .0 .02 NS NS 9... 9 8.3.2 - - So 58 8d 9.... EE .559? 38985 8d 2.9: 8.0 8+9 8d :8: 89¢ 23395-82 mmcmaxm 5o E...” :3 5mm :3 «mm-m $925 - 5% 5:2 8:253. :3 an... «.2. 8.8 :3 8... 9:85 9.6.8285qu 7.995 339.? 8... wim- ood $.8- 5... 5. Fm- .9865. 5% .58 8:959. 8.0 ovo- Ed 9d- 8d 93. 583 .o 3353 8d 58. cod 9. a- cod 8.8- 3.28 .0 029, .95563 8.0 85- cod N2”- 8d mod. 383 393585 05.980 8.0 9.2 cod 3.9 8.0 52 a 558» two «to- NE. 9d .2. NS- 659 5:65 3.8 8.0 N: 5.0 8.0 8... o: 93. .6 5.252 8... 3m 8... v3 cod 9... E3585 532 5:8 .o 35:59 cod and 8... end 8... ~00 use? 9.8.. 53m cod 8. F 8d a? 2:. BF 388 .9058“. ES mag-n. 9mE=mw mag-n. 99.5mm mag-n. 9mE=mm mm_nm_.m> .cmucmamns a. 993. a. 99.... E 993.. h-N 03¢... 115 Table 2.8 Gross benefit for issuing firms by credit ratings using the service of chosen syndicate rather than that of unchosen syndicate. The gross benefit is defined as the expected mean net yield (BPS) of bond issues, had they chosen the unselected syndicate minus the observed net yield of bond issues. The benefit estimated in column 1 (below the heading of Hybrid) is the predicted BPS of CB-Lead client by using the estimates of hybrid BPS regression reported in Table 2.6 minus the original BPS of CB-Lead client. Hence, the benefit in column 3 is estimated in the same way. CB-Lead stands for a commercial bank as the lead underwriter. Hybrid represents an investment bank as the lead undenivriter while other commercial banks are involved in an issue. PurelB stands for the underwriter syndicate includes only investment banks. The p-value of t-test (two-tailed) is reported, the tested null hypothesis is the gross benefit is equal to zero. Panel A. Gross benefit for clients of CB-Lead syndicate Hybrid Credit ratings Benefit P-value Benefit P-value All ratings -3.63 0.46 8.23 0.10 No. of observations 184 1 84 Aaa or Aa -21.46 0.03 -8.75 0.14 No. of observations 14 14 A or Baa 3.20 0.25 17.68 0.00 No. of observations 136 136 Ba or below 2364 0.33 -22.59 0.36 No. of observations 34 34 Panel B. Gross benefit for clients of hybrid syndicate CB-Lead Credit ratings Benefit P-value Benefit P-value All ratings 173.42 0.00 101.96 0.00 No. of observations 345 345 Aaa or Aa 202.26 0.00 102.78 0.00 No. of observations 46 46 A or Baa 168.39 0.00 100.98 0.00 No. of observations 215 215 Ba or below 170.50 0.00 104.03 0.00 No. of observations 84 84 116 Table 2.8 (Cont'd) Panel C. Gross benefit for clients of PurelB syndicate. Hybrid CB-Lead Credit ratings Benefit P-value Benefit P-value All ratings -11.10 0.00 137.08 0.00 No. of observations 798 798 Aaa or Aa -17.98 0.00 142.39 0.00 No. of observations 127 127 A or Baa -8.82 0.00 128.93 0.00 No. of observations 542 542 Ba or below -13.88 0.24 166.11 0.00 No. of observations 129 129 117 APPENDICES 118 APPENDIX A DATA DEFINITIONS A.1 Issue Characteristics CBL: A dummy variable that is 1 if the lead undenNriter is a commercial bank; 0 otherwise. The commercial banks represent the section 20 subsidiaries of bank holding companies, which are permitted to underwrite corporate securities by the Federal Reserve Board. Commercial Bank-Lead: If the lead underwriter is a commercial bank and there is no other commercial bank involved in the underwriting, then the assigned value is 1. Otherwise, it is 0. (There may or may not be an investment bank involved as a co—manager.) Commercial Bank-Coop: If the lead underwriter is a commercial bank and there are other commercial banks involved in the underwriting, then the assigned value is 1; 0 otherwise. CB-Lead: If the lead underwriter is a commercial bank with or without other commercial banks involved in the underwriting, the assigned value is 1; 0 otherwise. (This variable includes both Commercial Bank-Lead and Commercial Bank-Coop.) Hybrid: If the lead underwriter is an investment bank and there are other commercial banks involved in the underwriting, the assigned value is 1; 0 otherwise. 119 PurelB: If the lead undenNriter is an investment bank and there are no other commercial banks involved in the underwriting, the assigned value is 1; 0 otherwise. BPS: The basis points spread is the premium of the ex ante yield spread of a bond over the ex ante yield of a US. Treasury security of comparable maturity. Size of issue: The size of issue is the principal amount in millions of dollars. Maturity: It is the years to maturity. Non-investment grade: A dummy variable that is 1 if the Moody’s credit rating for the bond issue is Ba or below or not rated; 0 otherwise. Credit rating: If the Moody’s credit rating for the bond issue is Aaa or Aa, the assigned value is 1; if it is A or Baa, the value is 2, if it is non-investment grade, the assigned value is 3. Refinance bank debt: A dummy variable that is 1 if the purpose of the issue is to refinance existing bank debt; 0 otherwise. A.2 Firm Characteristics Total assets: Total asset (AT) in millions dollars. Interest expense relative to operating income: Interest expenses (XINT) divided by operating income before depreciation, depletion and amortization (OIBDP). Firm size: Natural log of market value of equity (MKVAL) in millions dollars. Operating income: Operating income before depreciation, depletion and amortization (OIBDP) divided by total assets, multiplied by 100. 120 Exchange listing: 1 means the stock of the company is listed on either NYSE or AMEX; 0 otherwise. Leverage: It is defined by total debt (DT) divided by total assets, multiplied by 100. Volatility of equity return: It is proxied by the variance of residuals from the market model, which is estimated over 120 trading trades prior to the issuing date. The return on the CRSP value-weighted index is used to proxy domestic market returns. Equity trading volume: Average trading volume (3 years average, CSHTR3) divided by common shares outstanding (CSHO). Tobin’s q: It is defined by the book value of debt (DT) plus market value of equity divided by total assets. Sales growth: The five-year lease square growth rate of sales (GSALES). Cash Reserves: It is defined by cash and cash equivalent (CHE) divided by total asset (AT) net of cash. Reduction of long-term debt: Reduction of long term debt (DLTR) in the year of bond issuing divided by total assets multiplied by 100. Refinance bank debt*high interest indicator: A dummy variable that is 1 if the purpose of issue is for refinancing bank debt and interest expense relative to operating income is above its median value. Refinance bank debt*interest expense: The interaction term between refinance bank debt and interest expense relative to operating income. 121 DUM91: Yearly dummy for 1991. Hence, all other years are defined in the same way. A.3 Estimated adjustment terms for the second stage regressions ¢(Z7) , which is estimated 1 - 2: :92: 02.002 :0: 20 252 E2800 0:0 m0_EE:0 >:00> 2: :0: 00:08:00 0:: 00:25:00 :.00:0 002022: 0.: E0: 00:02:00 20 00005 :0:00_0m m:0:0m00:0 2: _0::00 2 00m: 252 52500.60 0:0:0moncm .0E00:_ 0::2000 o: 02:22 00:00x0 7.225 ncm 500 5:00 00:0::0m :0 E22 8:00:25 2: m_ 00:00x0 6225.500 xcmn 00:09.0”. 0.00:? 0:: :0 :062: 2: :2: 2090. m_ 0E00:_ 0.52000 2 02:22 00:00x0 622:. :0 _0>0_ 05 t F m_ 03.0> 00:90.00 2: 0.00:? >580: 0 .5 68065 :0225 :9... 0052050 0 .30: 5:00 026:0 00:05.2 2 m_ 030$ :0 000050 2: t F m_ :2: 0.00:? >EE00 0 0_ E00 €00 00:0::0m 20000 .22 >0 000E: >300 :0 0:_0> :2:0E 03.0 300 :0 03.0> x000 2: >0 005.00 0_ 0 0.508 005550 0 .022 :0: :0 2,200 :0 mm 0_ 0:02 ::00 2: :0: 052 E20 m.>000_2 2: t F 0_ 002m E0E:w0>:_ :02 .0020 ::0E:m0>:_-:0: 2 z t .m m_ 03.0> 2: .00m :0 < m_ g t .N m_ 0:_m> 2: .0< :0 00.0. m_ 0:005 0:00 0:: :0: 05:2 2020 m.>000_2 2: t F 0_ 05:2 5020 00:05 :0::2:00:: 0E0: ::0E:m0>:_ 2: >_:0 000205 0.0E00 2: .m 2 m 02:20.: :_ 00:02 :0::2c0ncz xcmn _0_20EE00 25 000205 0.0800 0.: .v 2 F 0:55.00 :_ 202-: :0 002.0?0 0:0 0:22.052 3di 000200 E60 0300 0020-0:0000 :0 2:06.208 200 0.: :002 w 2 P 055.00 220:0: :0____E on: 0:05 :0 020 :062: 2: 2 .0000 :0 :2: .2020 0_ 0:05 :0 020 2: : :0::0E 0:00-30: 0:: mm 0050: m_ :0::0E 0:02 090. 2: 2.0335000» .002: 05052.: 5:5 9.53 E08302: >0 .0 0x000 .222:an 05 >0 :0§.E00:: 20:00 :0 000050 “500 2000 :o 00:0Ezmm .0 5.2.3.3 124 8: 8: v2 :2 28:28:: 8 .oz 2.: 2.: 8.: 8.: mm 8822 .. .. :0: 8.0- 3.: 8.:? 8.: 8.::- 58. .8888 880880 8.: 3.8: 8.: R8: 8.: 2:3 8.: 2:3 08.: 85825-82 00:00x0 8.: 8.8 8.: 2.8 8.: 5:2 8.: 8.8 7.925 .. so: 0.58 88:80 8.: 8.2 3.: 8.2 8.: 8.2. B: 8.8 0585 05828202802” 8.925 m_nmtm> 8.: 5.2- 5.: 8.:- 8.: 3.8. 8: 8.8- .2865: 50: 0.8: 8:28: 8.: 8.: . . 8.: 8.: . . 8:5 8 0508.. 8.: 8.8- 8.: 8.::- 8.: 8.8- 8.: 8.8- 858 8 03.0> 888:3 8.: 8.:- 8.: 8.0- . . 8.: :.:- 288 088585 8:980 8.: 2.2 8.: 8.2 . . 8.: 8.: a 058» 8.: 8.:- 8.: 8.:- 8.: 8.: 8.: 8.: :8: :59: 8.00 8.: 8.: 8.: 8.: 3.: 8.: 2.: 8.: 085 :o 5.252 3.00200: 8.: 8.: 8.: 8.: 8.: 8.: 8.: 8.: 522 5:8 8 5.8.8 8.: 8.: 8.: 8.: . .. 2.: mm:- 0522 :58: 580 8.: 2.: 8.: 8.: . . 5.: 8.:- e88 .5288 .28 00_0>-n_ 20E:0w 0:_0>-n_ 20E:wm 0:_0>-n_ 208:0w 0:_0>-n_ 208:0m xcmm ::0E:m0>:_ c: 000 xcmm E0E:m0>:_ 8v mam xcmm _0_20EE00 >3QO .0 8.2.83 xc0m .0_20EEoo €QO m0.00:0> E03303. 125 0000.05 20 >2: :0:0:: 02.002 :0: 20 05:0: ::20:00 ::0 00.55:: >..00> 0:: .0: 00:05:00 0: H .:0.:0E:00 :.00:0 000:0-:0:: 0:: 80.: 00:25:00 20 0000.0 8.8200 0:0:000::0 0:: 2:80 0: :00: 0E0: 3020200 00800005. 00:00:. 05:22.0 0: 02:02 00:00.0 0225 0:0 :00: ::00 00:05:00. :0 E0: 5:00.25 0:: 0. 00:00x0 0225-50: ::00 00:05:00. .0.00.:0> 0.:: :0 :0.:0E 0:: :0:: .000. 0. 2:005 05:0.000 0: 02:52 00:00x0 :0225 :0 _0>0_ 0:: :. F 0. 03.0> 020.000 0:: .0.00.:0> >EE:: 0 0. 8:00.05 :0225 :0... .00.2:0::0 o .:00: :.:00 050.0 00:0::2 0: 0. 0:00. :0 000050 0:: :. F 0. :0:: 0.00:0> >EE:: 0 0. :00: 5:00 00:05:20 0:0000 .20: >0 :0:.>.: >:.:.00 :0 0:_0> :0:..0E 00.0 :00: :0 0:.0> 0.000 0:: >0 :0::0: 0. 0 0.500..- 00.3.2.6 o .022 :0: :0 26.00 :0 0m 0. 0:00. ::00 0:: .0: 05:2 :.:20 0.>:00.2 0:: :. F 0. 0:20 ::0E:00>5-:0z .0020 ::0E:00>5-:0: 0. :. :. .0 0. 0:.0> 0:: .00m .0 < 0. :. :. .N 0. 0:.0> 0:: .20. .0 00< 0. 0:00. ::00 0:: .0: 05:2 :.:20 0.>:00_2 0:: :. F 0. 05:2 :.:20 00:00. :0:..8005 ::00 502008. 0:: 25 0000.05 0.05.00 0:: .m :E:.00 :_ 00:00. :0:..8005 0.:00 .0.0:0E500 >.:0 00:50:. 0.0000 0:: .F :E:.00 :. .:00:-: :0 000.0?0 0:0 0:0.00202 $02 000200 :500 0.000 000:0-000000 :0 2:22:08 0:00 0:: 0002 v 0: F 0:63.00 .256: :0.__:: 0va 0:00. :0 0N.0 :0.:2: 0:: :0:: 000. 0. 0:00. :0 0.00 0:: :. :0:..0E ::00 0:00.050: 0:: 00 :0::0: 0. :0:..0E 0:00. ..0E0 0: H 00000050000 .002: 0>.:0E0:_0 5.3 0:000 ::00-000E. >0 :0 00.000 .0.0:08800 0:: >0 02:...250003 00:00 :0 0:00:00 :50: 0.000 :0 00:0E.:0w ”:0:...05 0:00. =0Ew «0 8:58,: 126 000 00: 08002008 :0 .oz 000 00.0 «a 00:00:}: 0. 0 No.0 ::00. 8:0: ::08:0:_:0 009.0085 00.0 00.00: 8.0 00.00: 000:0 505002.802 00:00x0 00.0 00.00 Rd 2.3. 00.25 - 500 0:00 00:00.00: 00.0 3.0 F 00.0 050$ 08005 05:0:000:00:00x0 :00:0:5 :0.:0.:0> 00.0 00.00. 000 00.0- 5:00.05: :00: €00 00:00:00 :00 :30 Rd 00.0- .0000. :0 00.0-:03 8.0 00.00. 80 000:- .0500 :o 020) 00:05:03 8.0 00.? - - 0:00.00 0:20.085 0:00.000 00.0 05; - . 0 0.508 00.0 «to 00.: ~00 .0>-0: 52,90 0000 00.0 0: 8.0 :0: 0:00 :0 0020.2 8.0 00.0 8.0 000: 30:200.: 50:0: >530 :0 >:___:0_o> 00.: 0F: . :- 08:.0> 05:0: 355 8.0 00.0 . - 0:00.00 0:20:00 08F 0:_0>-n. 0:08.:0m. 00.03: 0:08.:0m 00.00.:0> ::0::000:c_ x000 ::08:00>c. x000 .0.0:08800 00 5.2.2.3 127 Appendix B3 Gross benefit for firm using the service of chosen underwriter rather than that of unchosen underwriter: Estimated from alternative model specification. The gross benefit is defined as the expected mean net yield (BPS) of bond issues, had they chosen the unselected underwriter minus the observed net yield of bond issues. The benefit estimated in column 1 (below the heading of Commercial Bank Clients) is the predicted BPS of commercial bank client by using the estimates of investment bank BPS regression (model 3) reported in Appendix B1 minus the original BPS of commercial bank client. Hence, the benefit in column 3 is estimated in the same way by using model 1 reported in Appendix B1. The p-value of t-test is reported, the tested null hypothesis is the gross benefit is equal to zero. Panel A. Gross benefit of full sample and by subperiods. Commercial Bank Clients Investment Bank Clients Years Benefit P-value Benifit P-value 1991-1996 3.56 0.48 128.39 0.00 No. of observations 184 1143 1991-1993 0.55 0.93 133.54 0.00 No. of observations 66 664 1994-1996 5.24 0.46 121.25 0.00 No. of observations 118 479 Panel B. Gross benefit by credit ratings Commercial Bank Clients Investment Bank Clients Credit ratings Benefit P-value Benefit P-value Aaa or Aa -15.09 0.02 139.21 0.00 No. of observations 14 173 A or Baa 13.08 0.00 121.74 0.00 No. of observations 136 757 Ba or below -26.85 0.28 143.22 0.00 No. of observations 34 213 Panel C. Gross benefit by the issue size (in million dollars) Commercial Bank Clients Investment Bank Clients Issue Size Benefit P-value Benefit P-value >= 150 -2.33 0.84 133.63 0.00 No. of observations 54 648 < 150 6.00 0.27 121.52 0.00 No. of observations 130 495 128 00:0.05 0:0 >00: :000:: 000000: :0: 0:0 08:0: ::0:0:00 ::0 00.880: >.:00> 0:: :0: 00:08:00 0: :- .08005 050000 0: 02:0.0: 00:00x0 :00:0::. ::0 :00: :.:00 00:05.0”. :0 8:0: :0.:00:0:5 0:: 0. 00:00x0 :00:0:5...:00: :.:00 00:05:0m .00.>>:0::0 o .:000 ::00 05:0.x0 00:0:00: 0: 0. 0000. :0 000800 0:: :. F 0. :0:: 0.00.:0> >880: 0 0. :00: :.:00 00:05:01 0:0000 .06: >0 000.2: >:_000 :0 00_0> :0::08 00.0 :00: :0 00_0> 0.000 0:: >0 005:0: 0. 0 0.500... 00.3050 0 .:0:0: :0: :0 26.00 :0 0m. 0. 0000. ::00 0:: :0: 05:0: :.00:0 0.>:00.2 0:: :. F 0. 000:0 ::08:00>5-:0z 000:0 ::08:00>5-:0: 0. :. :. .m 0. 00_0> 0:: .000 :0 < 0. :. :. .N 0. 00_0> 0:: .00. :0 00< 0. 0000. 0:00 0:: :0: 05:0: :.00:0 0.>:00.2 0:: :. F 0. 05:0: :.00:0 .00:00.::>0 0.05m .0> :.:0>I :0 :00.:00800 0:: 80:: 00:08:00 0. AN: :.:0>I :0: :05 .AF: 0.:0>_._ :0: 0:00.::>0 :.:0>... 0: 00:00800 0. 0:00.::>0 0000-00 :0:; :0.:08.:00 :.00:0 000:0-:0:: 0:: 80:: 00:08:00 0:0 0000.0 :0.:00_00 000:000::0 0:: .2800 0: :00: 08:0: ::08:00._:0 000:000::m. 00000. :0::.:2:0::0-:.:0>: 0:: >80 0000.05 0.0800 0:... .:00:-: :0 000.0>-0 ::0 0:0.000:00: $0.0: 0:00:00 :500 0.000 000:0-::0000 :0 0::0.0_..:000 0:00 0:: ::000: v 0: F 0:80.00 ::0: 2050300 00:00.00 000:000::0 5.3 0:00.0:>0 0.:0>: >0 005:3:0000 00:00 :0 008009.00: 0000.50 5.00 0.000 3:00.000 :0 00:05.:0m «0 50:08.4. 129 130 0:0 00 0000020000 :0 .oz 000 0:..0 .0. 00:00.00. 00.0 :00: 00.0 00.00- :00: 50500.00 0000000000 00.0 00.00: 00.0 00.00: 000:0 2050005002 00:00x0 00.0 00.0: 00.0 0000 :00:0::. . :000 ::00 02:05:00. 00.0 00.00 00.0 00.00 0800:. 0:.:0:000:00:00x0 :00:0::. .0.00.:0> 00.0 000:- 0:.0 00.00- 5:02:00 :00: 0.000 00:00:00 00.0 00.0 00.0 00.0 .0000. :0 00.0.03 00.0 00.00. 00.0 0:. :.0- .0.000 :0 0200 00:05:03 00.0 :0. :- :00 00. :- 0:0000 00:00:80. 0000000 00.0 00.: 00.0 00.0 0 0.0.00: 00.0 0:.0 00.0 00.0 ..:>-0: 526:0 00_00 :00 0:: 00.0 00.0 0000. :0 0020.2 00.0 3.0 00.0 0:.0 0000.00: 50:0: 0.000 :0 >:___:0_0> 00.0 0:.0 00.0 00.0 05200 00.00:: 0.000 :00 00.0- 00.0 00.0. 0:0000 0:00:00: 08: m:_m>-n_ 3mE=ww m:_m>-n_ 99::sz 0055.5) 50950.20:— .0: 25>: .:: 25>: 00 0000000. Appendix BS Additional estimation of gross benefit for issuing firms by credit ratings using the service of chosen syndicate rather than that of unchosen syndicate. This table reports additional estimation of gross benefit by using the BPS regression of PurelB syndicate without the endogenous adjustment term. The benefit estimated in column 1 (below the heading of CB-Lead clients) is the predicted BPS of CB-Lead clients by using the estimates of regression PurelB (3) reported in Table 2.7 minus the original BPS of CB-Lead clients. Hence, the benefit in column 3 is estimated in the same way for Hybrid clients. CB-Lead stands for a commercial bank as the lead underwriter. Hybrid represents an investment bank as the lead underwriter while other commercial banks are involved in an issue. PurelB stands for the underwriter syndicate includes only investment banks. The p-value of t-test (two-tailed) is reported, the tested null hypothesis is the gross benefit is equal to zero. CB-Lead Clients Hybrid Clients Credit ratings Benefit P-value Benefit P-value All ratings 9.84 0.05 6.92 0.05 No. of observations 184 345 Aaa or A3 -7.24 0.22 10.00 0.38 No. of observations 14 46 A or Baa 19.30 0.00 5.59 0.05 No. of observations 136 215 Ba or below -20.97 0.39 8.65 0.45 No. of observations 34 84 131 BIBLIOGRAPHY 132 Bibliography Anand, Bharat N. and Alexander Galetovic (1997), Information, non-excludability, and financial market structure, Working paper, Yale School of Management and Universidad de Chile. Ang, James S. and Terry Richardson, 1994, The undenivriting experience of commercial bank affiliates prior to the Glass-Steagall Act: A re- examination of evidence for passage of the act, Journal of Banking and Finance 18, 351-395. Beatty, Randolph P. and Jay R. Ritter, 1986, Investment banking, reputation, and the underpricing of initial public offerings. Journal of Financial Economics 15, 213-232. Berger, Allen M, Rebecca S. Demsetz and Philip E. Strahan (1999), The consolidation of the financial services industry: Causes, consequences, and implications for the future, Journal of Banking and Finance 23, 195- 214. Bharat, A. Jain and Omesh Kini, 1999, On investment banker monitoring in the new issues market, Journal of Banking and Finance 23: 49-84. Bhargava, Rahul and Donald R. Fraser, 1998, On the wealth and risk effects of commercial bank expansion into securities undewvriting: An analysis of Section 20 subsidiaries, Journal of Banking and Finance 22, 447-465. Bhattacharyya, Sugato and Vikram Nanda, 1998, Client discretion, switching costs and financial innovation, Working paper, University of Michigan. Billett Matthew Thayer, Mark J. Flannery, and Jon A. Garfinkel, 1995, The effect of lender identity on a borrowing firm’s equity return, Journal of Finance 50, 699-718. Boot, Amoud W. A., Todd T. Milboum and Anjan V. Thakor 1998, Expansion of banking scale and scope: Don't banks know the value of focus? Working paper, University of Amsterdam, London Business School, and University of Michigan. 133 Booth, James R. and Richard L. Smith, II, 1986, Capital raising, underwriting and the certification hypothesis, Journal of Financial Economics 15, 261-281. Carey, Mark, Mitch Post and Steven A. Sharpe, 1998, Does corporate lending by banks and finance companies differ? Evidence on specialization in private debt contracting, Journal of Finance, 53(3), 845-878. Chemmanur, Thomas J. and Paolo Fulghieri, 1994, Investment bank reputation, information production, and financial interrnediation, Journal of Finance, 49(1), 57-79. Chung, Ching-Fan, 1997, Estimating and testing polychotomous choice selectivity models under alternative distributional assumptions: Wages in the public and private sectors, Working paper, National Taiwan University. Cummins, J. David, Mary A. Weiss and Hongmin Zi, 1997, Organizational form and efficiency: An analysis of stock and mutual property-liability insurers, Working Paper Series of the Wharton Financial Institutions Center. Diamond, Douglas W., 1991, Monitoring and reputation: the choice between bank loans and directly placed debt, Journal of Political Economy, 99(4), 689-721. Diamond, Douglas W., 1991a, Debt maturity structure and liquidity risk, Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 709-737. Eccles, Robert G. and Dwight B. Crane, 1988, Doing Deals: Investment Banks at Work, Harvard Business School Press. Fama, Eugene F., 1985, What’s different about banks?, Journal of Monetary Economics 15, 29-39. Gande, Amar, Manju Puri Anthony Saunders, and lngo Walter, 1997, Bank underwriting of debt securities: modern evidence, Review of Financial Studies, 10(4), 1175 -1202. Gompers, Paul and Josh Lerner, 1998, Conflict of interest in the issuance of public securities: Evidence from venture capital, NBER Working Paper No. 6847. 134 Greenbaum, Stuart |., George Kanatas, and ltzhak Venezia, 1989, Equilibrium loan pricing under the bank-client relationship, Journal of Banking and Finance 13, 221-235. Holland, John, 1994, Bank lending relationships and the complex nature of bank- corporate relations, Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 21(3), 367-393. Hamao, Yasushi and Takeo Hoshi, 1997, Bank Underwriting of Corporate Bonds: Evidence from Japan after 1994, Working Paper, Columbia University and Osaka University. Houston, Joel and Christopher James, 1996, Bank information monopolies and the mix of private and public debt claims, Journal of Finance 51 (5), 1863- 1889. Jain, Bharat A. and Omesh Kini, 1999, On investment banker monitoring in the new issues market, Journal of Banking and Finance 23, 49-84. James, Christopher, 1987, Some evidence on the uniqueness of bank loans, Journal of Financial Economics 19, 217-235. Johnson, James M and Robert E. Miller, 1988, Investment banker prestige and the underpricing of initial public offerings, Financial Management 17, 19- 29. Kanatas, George and Jianping, Qi, 1998a, Underwriting by Commercial Banks: Incentive Conflicts, Scope Economies, and Project Quality, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30(1), 119-133. Kanatas, George and Jianping, Qi, 1998b, Underwriting by Commercial Banks: Incentive Conflicts, Scope Economies, and Project Quality, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30(1), 119-133. Khanna, Naveen and Sheri Tice, 1998, Wal-Mart's easy targets: A test of the chain store paradox. Working paper, Michigan State University and Tulane University. 135 Kroszner, Randall S. 1998, Rethinking bank regulation: A review of the historical evidence, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Summer 1998, 48-58. Kroszner, Randall S and Raghuram G. Rajan, 1997, Organization structure and credibility: evidence from commercial bank securities activities before the Glass-Steagall Act, Journal of Monetary Economics 39, 475-516. Maddala G. S., 1983, “Models with self-selectivity", Chapter 9 in Limited Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics, Econometrics Society Monographs No. 3, Cambridge University Press. Mohanram, Partha and Ashish Nanda, 1998, When do joint ventures create value, Working paper, Harvard Business School. Nanda, Vikram and Vincent A. Warther, 1998, The price of loyalty: An empirical analysis of underwriting relationships and fees, Working paper, University of Michigan and University of Chicago. Nanda, Vikram and Youngkeol Yun, 1997, Reputation and financial intennediation: An empirical investigation of the impact of the lPO mispricing on underwriter market value, Journal of Financial Intermediation, 6, 39-63. Nayar, Nandkumar and Michael S. Rozeff, 1994, Ratings, commercial paper, and equity returns, Journal of Finance 49(4), 1431-1449. Opler, Tim, Lee Pinkowitz, Rene Stulz, Rohan Williamson, 1999, The determinants and implications of corporate cash holdings, Journal of Financial Economics 52, 3-46. Pichler, Pegaret and William Wilhelm, 1998, A theory of the syndicate: Form follows function, Working paper, Boston College. Puri, Manju, 1994, The long-term default performance of bank underwritten security issues, Journal of Banking and Finance 18, 397-418. Puri, Manju, 1996, Commercial banks in investment banking: conflict of interest or certification role?, Journal of Financial Economics 40, 373-401. 136 Rajan, Raghuram G., 1992, Insiders and outsiders: the choice between informed and arm’s-length debt, Journal of Finance 47(4), 1367-1400. Saunders, Anthony, 1999, Consolidation and universal banking, Journal of Banking and Finance 23, 693-695. Sharpe, Steven A., 1990, Asymmetric information, bank lending, and implicit contracts: a stylized model of customer relationships, Journal of Finance 45(2). 1069-1087. Song, Wei-ling, 1999, Bank-entry benefits and regulation distortion in the corporate security undenrvriting business, Doctoral dissertation, Michigan State University. Titman, Sheridan and Brett Trueman, 1986, Information quality and the valuation of new issues, Journal of Accounting and Economics 8, 159-172, White, Lawrence, 1996, Technological change, financial innovation, and financial regulation in the US: The challenges for public policy, Working paper, Stanford University. 137 nICH I I IjjIIIjIIIIIIIIjIIIIIIIIjijijI“ 2? 13(31