5 w m. m w ( A mm :"m r .. .2: .. .- 9.x.» 3 .5. n 25...: 12.. H 5».} xfigefipffiméz .V .. || l'l \ I I ‘ l ‘ I ‘ I III‘ ‘ M o i “mun” ... .rarxcix minimMilliiniiiiliiiiim 2 v as a w 3 1293 00786 This is to certify that the dissertation entitled The Allocation of Aircraft Between Markets under Regulation and Deregulation presented by John Howard Brown has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D Economics degree in /W 5. K4541... Major professor Date W4? 4 /7// MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 LIBRARY Michigan State University 1 1 LA PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. J l l:L__J[:j ___|[:__Jl_J -l l- LJ .J l l MSU is An Affirmdivo AotiorVEquei Opportunity Indituion . mama-m THE ALLOCATION OF AIRCRAFT BETWEEN MARKETS UNDER REGULATION AND DEREGULATION BY John Howard Brown A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1989 A/V’III‘) lg)" 7 ABSTRACT THE ALLOCATION OF AIRCRAFT BETWEEN MARKETS UNDER REGULATION AND DEREGULATION BY John Howard Brown The work of Douglas and Miller prior to deregulation suggested that competition in flight frequency led the airlines to acquire larger stocks of aircraft,and particularly smaller aircraft, than were necessary in a deregulated environment. Stocks of aircraft acquired when regulation held fares above minimum levels of average cost were too large, since frequent flights require more aircraft. In addition, airline fleets contained too many smaller aircraft because the economies of aircraft size were not realized under regulation. The relationship between airline route structures and the fleets of aircraft possessed by airlines both before and after regulation is investigated here. The chief theoretical assertation of this dissertation is that airline behavior since deregulation is best understood in terms of the unique characteristics of aircraft as capital goods. It is asserted here that the major consequence of regulation of the airlines was they were not able to adopt efficient route structures, i.e. hubbing-and-spoking. (Hubbing-and-spoking is a method of increasing flight frequency which is treated as a problem of joint production.) Airline stocks of aircraft chosen to maximize profits under regulation were efficient in a deregulated environment since flight frequency remains a competitive variable. Several distinct strands of evidence are brought to bear on this question. First, analysis of route level data shows that the pattern of aircraft allocation subsequent to deregulation did not vary in a manner consistent with prederegulation prediction. Regression analysis is also performed using gross fleet composition data and route structure variables. These regressions indicate that, although the relationship between the numbers of aircraft in airline fleets and route structure variables changed with deregulation, the relative shares of each type of aircraft in relation to route structure was unchanged. The evidence is thus consistent with the hypothesis advanced in this dissertation. Copyright by JOHN HOWARD BROWN 1989 DEDICATED TO THE MEMORY OF HOWARD GRAHAM BROWN (1907-1987) HUSBAND, FATHER, GRANDFATHER, BUILDER ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Any modern work of scholarship is in reality a collaboration. Most of the contributors are acknowledged in the bibliography. However, two groups deserve special recognition. The first of these is the members of my guidance committee who, individually and collectively, have provided the assistance and constructive criticism necessary to transform a vague notion into an acceptable work of scholarship. As is usual, they cannot be held responsible for the shortcomings of this work. The other group is my family. My mother and my late father gave me much encouragement and material support throughout my academic career. My brother and my in-laws have also helped me through the rigors of my academic program. Most of all, my wife and son have been crucial to this achievement: my son, by being understanding when "Daddy can’t come out to play, he’s got a dissertation to write": and even more importantly my wife, who swore she would never put a husband through school. My thanks are owed to everyone for their assistance. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ix LIST OF FIGURES X INTRODUCTION 1 CHAPTER 1 - THE STRUCTURE OF THE PROBLEM 4 The Structure of Demand The Structure of Supply: The Capital Constraints CHAPTER 2 - AIRLINES IN THE ECONOMIC LITERATURE 12 CHAPTER 3 - THEORETICAL TREATMENT - AIRLINE DEMAND FOR AIRCRAFT 24 Differentiated Products Treatment of Airline Flights and Aircraft Demand A Model of Flight Scheduling Airline Response to Regulation Airline Response to Varying Aircraft Capacities Effects and Mechanisms of Price Discrimination Joint Products, and Rubbing and Spoking as Explanations of Airline Behavior Joint Products and Rubbing and Spoking From Theory to Empirical Specification Empirical Specification of the Relationship of Flights per Day to Route Characteristics vii Empirical Specification of the Relationship of Equipment Choice to Route Characteristics Empirical Specification of the Relationship of Fleet Composition to Route Characteristics Summary of Theoretical Results CHAPTER 4 - EMPIRICAL TESTS 76 The Relationship of Number of Flights to Route Characteristics Specific Aircraft Types and Route Characteristics Econometric Procedure Theoretical Expectations Analysis of Empirical Results The Effects of Route Structure on Fleet Selection Econometric Procedure Theoretical Expectations Analysis of Empirical Results Summary of Empirical Results CHAPTER 5 - CONCLUSIONS AND SUGGESTIONS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH 143 The Structure of the Industry Previous Economic Analysis of Airlines A Theory of Airline Behavior Empirical Models of Airline Behavior Welfare Implications and Suggestions for Additional Research APPENDIX 153 - Data Types and Sources BIBLIOGRAPHY 157 - LIST OF REFERENCES - GENERAL REFERENCES viii LIST OF TABLES TABLE 1 ALTERNATIVE SPECIFICATIONS OF THE RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN MARKET PARAMETERS AND NUMBER OF FLIGHTS TABLE 2 THE RELATIONSHIP OF NUMBER OF FLIGHTS PER DAY TO ROUTE CHARACTERISTICS TABLE 3 THE RELATIONSHIP OF AVERAGE SEATS PER FLIGHT AND ROUTE CHARACTERISTICS TABLE 4 COMPARISONS OF THEORETICAL PREDICTIONS AND EMPIRICAL RESULTS: ROUTE LEVEL DATA TABLE 5 FLIGHTS PER DAY -INDEPENDENT VARIABLES IN NATURAL FORM TABLE 6 ROUTE LEVEL DATA RESULTS 1974 & 1984 TABLE 7 THE RELATIONSHIP OF AVERAGE SEATS PER FLIGHT AND ROUTE CHARACTERISTICS - FLEET DATA TABLE 8 EQUATIONS RELATING ROUTE STRUCTURE AND NUMBERS OF AIRCRAFT PART A - ABSOLUTE VARIABLES PART B - RELATIVE VARIABLES TABLE 9 PANEL DATA RESULTS 1970-1984 TABLE 10 COMPARISON OF THEORETICAL PREDICTIONS AND EMPIRICAL RESULTS ix 65 81 84 90 98 107 111 112 125 128 LIST OF FIGURES FIGURE 1 AIRLINE FLIGHTS AS DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS IN A CIRCULAR MODEL FIGURE 2 POSSIBLE EQUILIBRIA - FULLY AND PARTIALLY SERVED MARKETS FIGURE 3 COMPARISON OF REGULATED AND COMPETITIVE EQUILIBRIA FIGURE 4 THE RELATIONSHIP OF AVERAGE COST PER MILE AND PER PERSON FOR A SINGLE VARIETY OF AIRCRAFT FIGURE 5 AVERAGE COST PER PASSENGER WITH THREE AIRCRAFT VARIETIES FIGURE 6 EQUILIBRIA WITH TWO AIRCRAFT VARIETIES FIGURE 7 THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FLIGHT FREQUENCY, FARES, AND NUMBER OF PASSENGERS PER FLIGHT FIGURE 8 SERVING SEVERAL MARKETS ON A SINGLE FLIGHT 28 34 37 40 42 44 53 59 INTRODUCTION The process of deregulation of domestic air transport in the United States has attracted considerable attention. There are several reasons for this. First, the domestic air transport industry in the United States, as in most countries, was "born regulated"; government policy has determined the structure and conduct of the industry from its very beginnings. Thus, the adjustments which the industry experiences as it moves towards a more competitive structure will indicate what the resource misallocation costs of regulatory intervention were. A second reason is that the deregulatory process is among the most advanced of the attempts at deregulation in this country in the past decade. In addition, the airline industry has been proposed as an industry closely fulfilling the requirements of contestability (Baumol and Bailey 1984). Although a great deal of attention has been paid to the process of deregulation, most of the literature has analyzed the effects of deregulation on the product 2 markets. Thus, pricing policy, route structure, and quality of service effects of deregulation have been analyzed intensively. Likewise, the effects on the labor force of the various carriers have been examined. However, little or no attention has been given to the changes which deregulation has or is likely to bring about in the airlines’ usage of aircraft types. This dissertation begins by analyzing the manner in which airlines can be expected to adjust their deployment of aircraft in deregulated markets. Previous treatments of the effects of airline regulation have not yielded accurate predictions about the nature of airline responses to deregulation. It is demonstrated below that this failure is the result of three flaws in previous treatments of airline industry behavior. The first flaw is that aircraft have been treated as homogeneous units of capacity. However, aircraft provide capacity which varies in quality from the point of view of both consumers and airlines. Second, it has been assumed that airlines would not vary their route structures after deregulation. In fact, previous treatments viewed routes in isolation rather than treating an airlines' route structure as a form of joint product. In addition, they have uniformly assumed that airlines will only charge a single fare to their customers, or at least only charge differential fares to the extent that such fares can be justified by differences 3 in service class. As demonstrated below, airlines have utilized a unique form of price discrimination as a part of their response to deregulation. This dissertation consists of five chapters. The first defines the problem. The second chapter is a literature review discussing in detail the relevant theoretical and empirical results which have been produced about the effects of airline deregulation on the deployment of capital equipment (i.e. aircraft). The third chapter outlines the model which is used to analyze these effects. The fourth chapter is devoted to empirical tests of this model. The fifth chapter summarizes the findings of this dissertation, analyzes the welfare effects of airline deregulation, and suggests some possible extensions of the theoretical and empirical work discussed herein. CHAPTER I THE STRUCTURE OF THE PROBLEM The airline industry exists to provide transportation services to consumers and businesses. These services can take the form of passenger or freight transportation, separately or jointly provided. Firms provide these services by combining labor, materials, and capital. Airline capital is largely embodied in the form of vehicles, the aircraft. These vehicles differ significantly from the form capital is usually conceived of in economic theory. Airline capital is "lumpy", that is, it is available only in discrete units. In addition, the vehicles are of different capacities in terms of both the number of passengers they are capable of carrying and their range. This has important effects on the cost structures of individual flights. The lumpiness of capital has important implications for the conduct of airlines. It implies airlines should 5 offer scheduled service. This permits potential passengers to plan their trips effectively (De Vany 1975). However, since flights are not continuously available, some passengers must accept departure times that are not their preferred times. This fact of life for air passengers is acceptable only because scheduled service can be supplied at a much lower cost than individualized but unscheduled service. When regulation was established in the 19305, the existing (trunk) airlines were granted authority to operate on the routes which they operated at the start of regulation (grandfathered). All other attempts to begin operations in city-pair markets were subject to approval by the Civil Aeronautics Board (CAB). Likewise, the fares which airlines were permitted to charge were brought under CAB regulation.1 The demand for aircraft, like that for all factors of production is a derived demand. Consequently, the price and incentive distortions imposed by regulation of the product markets are expected to distort the airline's investment decisions also. When the process of deregulation began, the airlines possessed stocks of aircraft suited to maximize profits under the regulatory constraint. Since the lead time for new aircraft orders is from three to five years, the 1 There are many excellent discussions of the regulatory process as it existed prior to deregulation, such as Levine 1987. For this reason I do not discuss the process in any detail here. 6 airlines were forced in the short run to change their patterns of equipment utilization rather than discard obsolescent aircraft and replace them with technically appropriate types. The process of adaption to the newly deregulated environment is the object of this study. In the following subsections, we consider more formally the elements of the markets for air transport which define the nature of the problem. The Structure of Demand In general, there are two major dimensions in the demand for airline services. The first dimension is, of course, price. The second major dimension is quality. This variable, or more properly, this set of variables, is of considerable importance in determining the overall level of demand for air transport. The complexity of quality as a variable has discouraged a complete treatment of it as an element in demand. Thus, such important aspects of air travel quality as passenger comfort (including, e.g. seat width, aisle arrangements, and in-flight service) have received scant attention (cf. Bennett 1984). In fact, the only element of quality to receive extensive treatment--flight frequency--is really another element of the opportunity cost of travel. Under the usual assumptions of utility maximization and full information, consumers choose those goods which are lowest priced. The 7 money price is not the only important variable in determining the opportunity cost of travel.2 Indeed, if it were, there would be little or no demand for air transport, since it almost always suffers a price disadvantage relative to other modes of transportation. The other and more important element in determining the opportunity costs of air transport is the time savings that air travel confers relative to other modes of transportation. This time element in the opportunity costs of air travel is affected by the necessity of scheduling mentioned above. In brief, since airline capacity is lumpy, carriers must offer scheduled service in order to allow their customers to plan their itineraries. To quote DeVany, "There are two significant consequences of the discreteness of airline capacity. First, it makes scheduling the most efficient means of offering capacity by allowing the passenger to preplan his activities. Second, the discreteness of capacity means that there will always be intervals between flights, and, therefore, an interval between a passenger's desired departure time (a stochastic variable) and the time he actually departs on a flight." (1975,328) The fact of scheduling a departure at a particular 2 The literature on airline demand frequently refers to the combination of fare and time costs as the "full" costs of flying. Here, except when specifically citing previous literature, I will use the term opportunity cost., 8 time means that some potential passengers will not be able to depart at their preferred time. Thus, convenience of service is important to the demand for air transport, particularly where the time savings it offers is not great relative to alternative modes. Another important aspect of this demand structure is that preferred departure times are not uniformly distributed over the course of any period. Instead, demand is subject to regular "peaking." This gives rise to one of the important characteristics of the airline industry. The industry produces an almost endlessly varied offering of differentiated products.3 Each city pair between which air transport is offered defines a product class. Each departure time between any given city pair defines a distinct product. While the airline products in any city pair product class (i.e. differing departure times) are good substitutes they are not the same product.4 This imperfect substitutability coupled with the temporal variation in demand gives rise to some interesting strategic problems for airlines in their scheduling of flights. T uctur ° ' a 'n s 3 It nonetheless remains an industry on the criterion of Boyer (1984) i.e. all suppliers of air transportation services must be members of the producer cartel for cartelization to be effective. 4 Winston argues for a similarly disaggregate approach to transportation in the treatment of both costs and demand (1985, particularly 64-65). 9 The second blade of the Marshallian scissors, the supply of air transport services, is largely dictated by the capital available to provide them. The first major limitation imposed by the capital is that it is available only in discrete units. Some of the implications of this have already been touched upon, for example, that optimizing behavior implies scheduling of services. Yet another implication is that the costs of providing airline services consist of three distinct types. These are overhead costs; direct passenger, or traffic, costs; and what are commonly called capacity, or flight, costs (Douglas and Miller 1974, particularly 18-26). Capacity costs arise because a large proportion of the costs of employing a particular aircraft on any given route are not affected by the actual number of passengers carried on the flight. This distinction is made by the airlines as the difference between Available Seat: Miles, or capacity, and Revenue Seat: Miles, or actual transportation services provided. Capacity costs are fixed with respect to any given flight (i.e., once the aircraft and route are chosen). Thus airline markets are served with declining average costs when the number of passengers rises, at least up to the capacity of the largest available aircraft. Since the airline product was defined above as transportation between city pairs at a particular time, the individual flight has the cost characteristics of a natural monopoly. Many airline markets (city pairs) may be natural 10 monopolies if traffic density is so thin that competing flights can only be offered at increased average cost per Revenue Passenger Mile. This is, however, determined by the interaction of supply and demand. Another important effect of capital on the provision of airline services arises because of the specific forms in which the capital is embodied. There are economies of aircraft size. All other things equal, the average cost of an Available Seat Mile falls as the size of aircraft on a given route rises. In addition, the average cost per mile of an Available Seat Mile declines as the distance covered on a route increases. The nature of airline capital also contributes to another supply-side aspect of airline service. Airlines produce a product which is necessarily differentiated. However, the capital used to provide it is not specialized to the provision of any particular product or product class, as these concepts are described above. Aircraft can be freely transferred between markets. This, coupled with the necessity of providing gate and ground services in any market served, means that the provision of airline services is marked by substantial economies of scope.5 Thus, substantial competitive advantages accrue to firms which offer air transport services in a network. _ This tendency is reinforced by the peculiarity of demand that travelers not able to make direct connections between their origin and destination prefer to make all stages of their journey 11 with a single firm.6 (Johnson, 1985) Airline markets possess many features which make them differ from the sorts of markets which are usually subject to theoretical analysis in economics. Regulation added yet another layer of complexity. Both price charges and service entry on routes were regulated. The analysis of the effects of the combination of the industry's unique characteristics and of its regulation which has developed in the literature is the subject of the next chapter. 5 These economies of scope arise most clearly because of the existence of indivisibilities in the provision of gate and ground service. This in itself should not necessarily result in competitive disadvantage to firms offering only single city-pair service since time-sharing arrangements should be possible. In practice, however, most airlines seem to treat these services as indivisible. 6 Note: This peculiarity, so—called, in demand is probably a result of rational decision making on the part of the consumers of airline trips--minimizing connections also minimizes the wedge for "Murphy’s law." CHAPTER 2 AIRCRAFT UTILIZATION IN THE ECONOMIC LITERATURE As mentioned in the introduction, the airline industry has been the subject of a considerable amount of economic analysis. Interest in the airline industry preceded the process of deregulation. Indeed, the analysis of economists was instrumental in providing the rationale for deregulation. In contrast, there has been far less economic analysis of the employment of aircraft by airlines. This chapter surveys and critiques the available literature. There are two distinct strands to be considered in the literature. First, aircraft are chosen by airlines to provide certain performance characteristics in light of the airlines existing route system. In addition, the existing fleets of aircraft must be redeployed properly as the conditions in markets and the structure of an airlines routes change. When regulated, both price and route structure are 12 13 fixed. Thus, the airline planner has only two interrelated decision variables--flight frequency, and vehicle type to be employed. Since the route structure is known, the choice of airline fleets is based on choosing a fleet which offers optimum performance on the existing routes. Peyrelevade (1969) was the first to consider the problem. He produced a method for computing the optimal structure of an airline fleet given the set of routes to be served. Unfortunately, his method is limited by two factors. First, the quantity of flights demanded is parametric. The effects of price and flight frequency on demand are not even considered. In addition, there is no treatment of rivalrous behavior on the part of airlines. The failures of the work discussed above are addressed in the work of Douglas and Miller (1974). They hypothesize that firms respond to regulatory constraints on price by offering greater flight frequency. Flight frequency is a competitive tool since greater flight frequency reduces the opportunity cost of flying. Given their model, Douglas and Miller explicitly discuss the rules for optimal allocation of aircraft among markets. Their model implies the following behavior with respect to allocation of aircraft. When all other things are equal: 1)Larger aircraft should serve more dense routes (density is in this case measured in emplanements per unit of time). 14 2)Larger aircraft should serve longer haul markets (Those where the time savings air travel confers are greatest). 3)Larger aircraft should serve markets where passenger value of time is low. Douglas and Miller verify that these guidelines for efficient allocation of aircraft are violated by airlines in the regulated environment. They found, in particular, that load factors were the lowest, and average costs therefore the highest, on the most dense of the transcontinental routes. This was a result of the mechanism for fare computation developed by the CAB, the Standard Industry Fare Level (SIFL). The SIFL formula did not fully reflect the lower costs incurred by airlines when serving transcontinental routes. This encouraged excessive flight frequency, both absolutely and relative to shorter haul routes. Pollack (1977) offers a critique of the existing methods of fleet planning, describing those elements which he asserts have been insufficiently considered in developing fleet planning models. There is no specific technique or conclusion cited: instead, there is a general discussion of the elements needed to construct an adequate fleet plan. Baumol et a1. (1982, 7) suggest that the contestability of airline city-pair markets leads to efficient allocations of aircraft on routes. Since 15 aircraft are "...virtually 'capital on wings’...," firms which do not use the most efficient type of aircraft for a route will suffer entry by entrepreneurs seeking economic profits. Ironically, since their book largely deals with the topic, this argument ignores the economies of joint production which airlines can enjoy by restructuring their routes as hub-and-spoke systems. Graham et al, discuss the evolution of the airline industry since deregulation. They offer a test of the Douglas and Miller excess-capacity hypothesis. They assert that the hypothesis "... implies that if there were economies of scale at the market level, load factors should have risen most in denser markets, ceteris paribus, as the result of deregulation"(1983 126-7). Their reported empirical results indicate that the effects of density on load factors did not change in the expected direction with deregulation. The papers discussed above were mostly completed before the process of deregulation was well begun and assume that airlines view their route structures as fixed and beyond their control. After deregulation, planners must take into account a much wider range of variables. Thus, in place of a single price (or small set of prices) on a given route and a fixed route network, planners must choose routes served, schedules offered, and the pricing formula used. Aircraft choice remains an important problem for the airlines. 16 The extent to which airlines wish to alter their stock of vehicles depends in large part on environmental factors beyond the airlines direct control. For instance, the rapid increases in fuel costs in the late 19705 made fuel economy a primary consideration in fleet planning. These fuel-cost considerations interact with other costs of operation of a particular type of aircraft in determining the actual composition of an airlines fleet. "In 1978 aviation fuel cost $1.50 a gallon in America and interest rates were at 6%. Then it was easy to persuade airlines to buy efficient new aircraft (hence the peak in deliveries in 1981). After all, on McDonnell Douglas's calculations fuel accounted for 46% of the cost of flying 2,000 nautical miles: operating costs such as wages and landing fees another 30%: and ownership-paying off the price of the aircraft-only 24%. By last year, things had changed. Fuel was down to 88 cents a gallon and interest rates were up to 12%. The result was that fuel accounted for only 31% of a route’s cost and ownership a daunting 36%. ...United Airlines, the world’s biggest carrier, is still operating its first Boeing 727, bought more than 20 years ago. When interest rates are high and fuel prices low, economic obsolesence recedes to the horizon." (Economist 818) Of course, airlines may also purchase used equipment. 17 Used airliners are usually cheaper. "A used aircraft's price tracked 15 to 20 percent below the price of a new model of the same aircraft" (F1 in , March 1984, 64-66). Thus the capital costs for used aircraft can be significantly lower. This possibility can carry much weight in airline decision making, thus, "A 757 covers the route from La Guardia to Houston in about the same time and carries about the same number of passengers as a 727- 200....But the public doesn’t care whether the machine costs $35 million or $7 million” (Flying, cc, cic.). In either case, the same factors are important in making decisions regarding fleet composition. First of all, "...airlines tailor their fleets to their routes" (Eccnomist, 1985). In doing so, they trade off among factors like trip costs and seat-mile costs, specific fuel consumption and fuel burn, over a set distance, payload and range, and "price per seat". In an application of these principles, Thayer notes, "...for Braniff’s domestic route system and for some of our Latin American routes, the advanced 727-200 fills the needs well. This aircraft meets the requirements of markets with low density and heavy business travel: it meets schedule requirements of multiple frequencies and limited capacity per trip: and it meets equipment requirements of low operating cost and appropriate capacity.” (James, 279-280) 18 As the preceding discussion indicates, airline choice of aircraft is centered on profit maximization. Profit maximization is also the central concern when determining what sort of route structure to serve. The exact nature of the adjustments of route structure to deregulation is the concern of Morrison and Winston (1985). They provide a simple model of the behavior of intercity route structures after deregulation. They suggest that profit-maximizing firms alter their route structures according to a simple principle. If the cost savings of serving a route jointly with some other route are great enough to offset the revenue lost because demand falls on the jointly served route due to decreased convenience of service, the new joint route should be adopted. Thus, economies of scope are the crucial determinant of the routes adopted. In particular, when there exist economies of vehicle size, economies of scope are likely to exist. Such economies may lead to joint provision of service (hubbing and spoking). However, if the economies realized are insufficient to offset the decreased convenience of service, route structures are likely to remain linear. Their discussion does not consider any strategic elements that exist in firm decisions on route structures and their ultimate configuration. Bailey and Baumol (1984) also note the presence of economies of scope in the provision of airline services. They assert that contestability in airline markets results 19 in the restructuring of airline route systems as hub and spoke systems. They note that the drastic increases in fuel prices experienced between 1978 and 1981 rendered many multi— engine jets technologically obsolete. This created excess capacity, which they expect to result in substantial price warfare. Such price warfare is not in accord with the theory of contestablility but is seen as a transitional phase in the evolution of the airline industry to its ultimate deregulated structure. Crandell suggests that stage length, trends in emplanements, and interdependence of routes are important factors in the process of deciding the routes to be served (James 1982, 231-232). In addition, he suggests that size, cost, fuel economy and environmental restrictions all play a role both in the short and longer term capital decisions of airlines. Also stressed is the importance of maximizing stage length in scheduling, since short hauls. are more expensive per mile and imply that a larger proportion of the aircraft’s day is spent on the ground. Thayer also stresses the importance of long stage lengths. In addition, he stresses the importance of high density for profitable operation on a route (James, 265). Aircraft selection is, in his words,"...the fulcrum of this scheduling concept." Selection is made with the end of achieving low cost per seat-mile through high utilization of equipment and productivity, frequent service, and the 20 capture of flow-through traffic. Particular stress is laid on the necessity of providing passengers with convenient connections on the carrier's own flights. The logical outcome of the concern with establishing on-line connections is the hub-and-spoke pattern of routing that emerged with deregulation. As Bailey et a1, note, ”The hubbing carrier serves more passengers on its flights so it can use larger aircraft at higher load factors. Its greater traffic may also enable it to offer more frequent flights" (1985, 74). They present evidence showing that flights have increased (p. 84). Flight frequencies are shown to have risen substantially for large hubs connecting to other large hubs, also for both other size classes of hubs and for non-hubs connecting to large hubs. 0n the other hand small hubs and non-hubs have lost interconnections both among themselves and with medium hubs. This suggests a decline in the ability, in general, to complete direct connections which were previously achievable. The increased overall flight frequency reported appears contrary to the beliefs held before deregulation that carriers offer too large an amount of flight frequency while regulated. In fact, it is not, since those predictions assume an unchanged route structure. Freedom of exit and entry makes that assumption invalid. Thomchick (1978) attempts to determine the characteristics which make existing airline routes 21 profitable or unprofitable. These route characteristics and a model of firm behavior are employed to determine which of a sample of routes are likely to be served after deregulation. 0n the basis of these techniques, she offers a series of hypotheses about the evolution of airline route structures after deregulation. First, small communities close to hub airports lose the services they previously received, as do routes which are less than 200 miles long. A second prediction is that quality of airline service will vary in certain predictable ways. For instance, she infers that airlines will offer more one-stop flights in place of multi stop flights. However, she also asserts that more non-stop flights will be offered, which does not appear to be the case. She also asserts that smaller aircraft will be employed to increase the frequency of flight service. Finally, in discussing how the industry as a whole will change, she predicts that airlines will include large numbers of small- and medium- sized aircraft in their fleets and commuter airlines will become more important providers of service. Thus, the behavior which she predicts is almost exactly opposite the predictions of Douglas and Miller. Bailey, Graham, and Kaplan, in their evaluation of the effects of deregulation, note that part of the reason for the low fares experienced by airlines after deregulation "...was the excess supply of equipment, and most notably wide-bodied equipment during the recession" (1985, 62). 22 They contend that "...regulation encouraged service competition, [thus] carriers faced incentives to purchase a larger stock of equipment than they needed. The freedom to exit and enter markets allowed carriers to more efficiently employ their narrow-bodied equipment, further exacerbating the excess supply of wide bodies....Three- and four-engine wide-bodied equipment was especially in excess supply. The Board’s regulatory policy set fares in dense long- haul markets well above costs. Yet this equipment can only be efficiently deployed in these markets." (13-62) To summarize the preceding discussion, it was generally recognized before deregulation that airlines had adopted inefficient patterns of aircraft utilization. However, the predictions of airline behavior after deregulation gave insufficient recognition to the efficiencies which airlines could achieve through changing their route structures. The key factor is that vehicles are capable of providing low average costs on routes given the densities attained on those routes. The general status of belief about the relationship between regulation and aircraft size is that plane sizes would rise following deregulation, that is, that regulation encouraged aircraft that were too small. But these theories were all based on the assumptions of a fixed-route 23 structure. Once the possibility of varying routes is admitted, the predictions of the effect of deregulation should have been much different. In the next chapter theoretical models will be presented which seek to explain the changes in airline utilization of their aircraft subsequent to deregulation in terms of these principles. CHAPTER 3 THEORETICAL TREATMENT - AIRLINE DEMAND FOR CAPITAL Previous treatments of airline deregulation have been flawed because they assumed that, upon deregulation, firms would only vary the number of flights offered on a fixed set of routes. Such treatments imply that, with deregulation, firms would abandon their dependence upon flight frequency as a competitive weapon, substituting price competition. They also predict that smaller communities might lose service because competition on profitable routes would eliminate the cross-subsidies that existed under regulation. In addition they assume that, under deregulation, airlines would charge a single fare, or would differentiate fares only according to class of service. These adjustments to deregulation imply that, under regulation, airlines respond to regulatory constraints by making inappropriate decisions about their aircraft stocks. 24 25 In particular, airlines forced by regulation to compete with flight frequency tend to use smaller aircraft than those competing on price and maximizing without constraint. They also have stocks of aircraft that are too large for markets where price and entry are not regulated. In addition, airlines under regulation faced a fare structure intended to cross-subsidize by permitting fares well above costs on long-haul routes. Since rents were available on long-haul service, these were exactly the routes most likely to experience frequency competition. Thus, the changed environment created by deregulation was expected to induce airlines to replace their smaller craft with larger aircraft capable of flying longer stages. This chapter establishes a theoretical framework to analyze the developments in the airline industry subsequent to deregulation. This framework permits a comprehensive approach to the problems of airline capital allocation, including a useful approach to empirical specification. This chapter contains three major sections. The first presents a simple method of characterizing the demand faced by airline firms in a competitive market. The analysis is based on a model developed by Salop (1984). However, only the first section is directly based on Salop's model: the balance of the chapter is entirely new. The results derived from this model allow inferences about the nature of airline capital demand. The second section extends the model to treat the supply response of airlines where they 26 are permitted to hub and spoke. The third section develops the empirical specifications which will be employed in the next chapter. A fourth section summarizes the results derived in the chapter. Differentiated Products Treatment of Airline Flights and Aircraft Demand A Model of Flight Scheduling We begin with a consideration of the demand for air service on a particular route. We suppose that a consumer makes a choice between an outside good (for present purposes this may be . considered an alternative transportation mode) and a differentiated good.l In addition, the consumer chooses the exact variety of the good to purchase. Because there are fixed costs of providing any variety of a good, "custom made" types of the good cannot be produced. The customer will purchase the commodity only if the cash price plus the opportunity cost of not getting precisely the desired variety of the commodity is less than his or her reservation price. In the case of airline service this opportunity cost can be quantified much more exactly than with other varieties of a 1 The original inspiration for this model is Stephen Salop’s "Monopolistic Competition with Outside Goods"(1978). However, Salop specifically denies the realism of the product characterization that he employs. 27 differentiated product. The displacement from the preferred good is a departure time different than the preferred time, the cost of which is the wage of the individual displaced times the time differential. In developing this model, we make the simplifying assumption that all consumers have identical preferences for the competing goods. Additionally, the consumers are assumed to be uniformly distributed on the circumference of a circle where each point on the circle represents a possible variety of the differentiated good. Different positions on the circumference of the circle are considered to represent the times of departure available throughout the course of a day. (This situation is represented in Figure 1.) All consumers have identical costs of being displaced from their preferred product. Using these assumptions, we can develop two distinct demand equations for varieties of the differentiated good in this market.2 Each variety of the good will have an identical demand equation because customers are distributed uniformly throughout the market. In the analysis which follows, each flight (i.e., variety of the good) is considered to be supplied by an individual profit- maximizing firm. Each variety’s demand curve is thus a firm-demand curve. This assumption has the virtue of considerably simplifying the analysis which follows, 2 Salop characterizes these as the "monopoly" and "competitive" demands. 28‘ DUE E) mu III]? GE] IND meow anomms fl sasssms sszamvs as sssmvssrss assesses a censuses HEDEE IBFF 29 although it is clearly not very realistic. The first demand equation arises when not all customers in the market are served. In this case, there would be some times of day when customers would resort to alternative modes of transportation. Another way of describing this situation is that, when the price of a flight in an incompletely served market changes,‘ only the quantity demanded for that flight changes. Other flights in the market are not affected. This demand function takes the form: 2L (1) = —(R-P) 0‘» T where qp is quantity demanded if not all customers in the market are served, L is total number of consumers in the market, and T is the opportunity cost per unit of displacement from a preferred product (in this case, it is the value of time wasted by the consumer because a flight at the preferred time is not available). In addition, R is the consumer's reservation price. Its value is determined by the opportunity cost, again in terms of the consumer's time used for travel, of the best alternative mode of transportation. Finally, p is the price paid for the transportation service. When all customers are served,the demand function becomes: (2) q,=i’(p'--E-p) 30 where, L,T,and p are defined as before, qI is the quantity demanded when all preferred times of departure are served by a flight, p‘ is the price charged on competing flights, that is, flights whose departure times are closest to the time of the flight in question, and n is the number of flights per day in the market.3 In this model, a fully served market is one in which no potential customer chooses to buy the alternative good. The notion of a fully served market arises because the condition of identical costs of displacement from the preferred variety of the differentiated good is imposed on consumers. The identical cost assumption has considerable merit in simplifying the theory which follows but no appreciable merit as a characterization of any real market. These two types of demand must be combined in a single demand curve faced by a flight serving this market and characterized by a "kink" where the two segments join. This occurs in spite of the Nash conjectures employed by the flights in the market, itself a remarkable result. Given these demand characterizations and the assumptions about the nature of flight costs presented below, it is possible to determine a Symmetric Zero Profit Equilibrium (SZPE) for this market. In other words, in equilibrium there are no economic profits earned, thus no entry, and each firm will produce the same output, that is, 3 For a development of these demand characterizations from first principles, consult Salop op. cit. 31 carry the same number of passengers on a flight. Each flight, which acts as a profit maximizing firm, is assumed to have total costs of the form: (3) C = mg + F where C is total costs of the flight and m is marginal cost per unit of realized demand, that is, per passenger carried, assumed to be constant at all levels of demand. In this case, these are the costs associated with transporting one more passenger, for example, ticketing, baggage handling, and in—flight meals. F is the fixed cost of providing service, characterized in the airline literature as flight costs. It depends on the route flown, or, distance, and the type of aircraft employed on the route. The conditions for a SZPE are: d (4) p+q<—p)sm dq and: (5) p=m+E q In other words, marginal revenue must not exceed marginal cost and price must be equal to average cost so that no economic profits are earned. This is so because individual flights are thought of in this analysis as monopolistic competitors whose zero profit equilibrium will pct be achieved at the minimum of average total cost. Since the equilibrium must be symmetric, and 32 assuming it has no gaps (i.e., unserved customers) it will be true that: (5) q = 3"." The derivative of each segment of the demand function, where the number of flights is fixed at the equilibrium number of flights on the route, can be calculated as: dqb T and: (7b) 2?. = II. dqf I. for the incompletely- and completely-served segments of a flight’s demand curve, respectively. Combining these derivatives with the equilibrium conditions and equation (6), it is possible to solve for the equilibrium price and number of products offered (here flights per day) for both completely and incompletely served markets. These are: (8a) pp=m+—I— an and (8b) ‘5 = m + PM 33 for the equilibrium prices and: (9a) nP= IL 25 and (9b) n‘= T—L- F for the number of flights offered in equilibrium.4 In addition to equilibria where the markets are either completely or incompletely served, there exists the possibility of an equilibrium at the "kink" where the two demand segments join. Since no tangency is possible at the "kink," a range of parameter values will be consistent with an equilibrium at the kink. The upper bound of these values is the partially served equilibrium where the demand and average cost curves are just tangent, or: (10) R-2m= : \L The lower bound is the upper limit for tangency in r11 fully served equilibrium, or: 1112 2L (11) R-m= The three possible equilibrium outcomes of the model are illustrated in Figure 2. Considering the choice by an 4 In this expression, n9 is in fact only the upper limit of the number of products which may be offered in the market. This reservation will be true of all the incompletely served markets considered below. P1 P2 P3 34 RC 1. 'C 2 0.1. oz _ FIGURE 3 POSSIBLE EQUILIBRIQ" FOR AN INDIVIDUAL FLIGHT 35 airline of aircraft to fly a particular route, the number of aircraft used is obviously a direct function of the number of flights (np,n')which a market will support. Airline Responses to Regulation In this section, the model is altered to consider the case of an exogenous price. This alteration reflects the situation faced by airlines during the regulatory period when the CAB controlled both the price of the airlines services and the routes on which the airlines were able to offer service. Thus the model also holds route structure constant, and only the number of flights which can be offered will be varied. Price is set at the level p“ which the firms accept as a given in their maximization process. As a result the zero profit equilibrium condition is altered to: (12) Prqr=mqr+ F Here qr is the equilibrium quantity demanded realized at the fixed price pr. Rearranging this expression yields: (13) <1r = F/ (Pr - 111) Remembering that if the entire market is served, q = L/n and q = qr, then the number of flights offered is : (14) n=L/[538+134 RPE+BSASL n-1 + Z c,l§ + 8 1:1 Since these are panel data each year was identified by a unique dummy variable. Each of these was assigned a value of one for that year and zero for all other years. These dummies control for such unobserved common effects on industry behavior as business cycle effects and industry growth trends (Fomby, Hill, and Johnson 1984). The results of the regressions using average number of seats is shown in table 7. Selected regression results for specific aircraft types are shown in table 8. This table is divided into two sections. In the first, the dependent variable is the number of aircraft of each type present in an airline's fleet. In the table these are referred to as absolute variables, since the absolute number of a type of aircraft in an airline’s fleet is the dependent variable. Five types of aircraft were present in significant quantities in airlines’ fleets during the sample period. These are two-, three-, and four-engine regular-bodied jet aircraft, and three- and four-engine wide-bodied jet 111 TABLE 7 THE RELATIONSHIP OF AVERAGE SEATS PER FLIGHT AND ROUTE CHARACTERISTICS- (VARIABLES IN NATURAL FORM) FLEET DATA DEPENDENT AVERAGE NO. AVERAGE NO. AVERAGE NO. VARIABLE SEATS 63-84 SEATS 63-75 SEATS 76-84 CONSTANT 67.047* 68.076* 75.230* 7.651 7.515 12.408 NO. LARGE 1.331* 1.383* 1.272* HUBS 0.428 0.492 0.643 NO. MEDIUM -2.913* -2.057* -3.864* HUBS 0.377 0.475 0.531 NO. SMALL -0.211 -0.418 -0.119 HUBS 0.233 0.250 0.409 STAGE 0.0950* 0.0696* 0.133* LENGTH 0.0084 0.0106 0.0119 REVENUE PASSENGER 0.00139* 0.00128* 0.00160* EMPLANEMENTS 0.00028 0.00046 0.000354 R-SQUARED 0.836 0.765 0.862 ADJ R-SQ 0.819 0.737 0.841 F-STATISTIC 47.907* 27.506* 42.225* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 ALL EQUATIONS SIGNIFICANT AT THE 99% LEVEL. COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. UNDERLINED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICENTS ARE REPORTED BELOW THE COEFFICIENT. STARRED 112 TABLE 8 EQUATIONS RELATING ROUTE STRUCTURE AND NUMBERS OF AIRCRAFT IN AN AIRLINES FLEET PART A TABLE 8-PART A ABSOLUTE VARIABLES SECTION 1 - TWO-ENGINE REGULAR BODIED JETS DEPENDENT NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES VARIABLE 1963-1984 1963-1977 1978-1984 CONSTANT -1.733 2.642 50.796* 7.705 3.365 15.891 NUMBER OF -0.836* -1.143* -1.603* LARGE HUBS 0.431 0.424 0.825 SERVED NUMBER OF -0.0662 -1.028 -0.256 MEDIUM HUBS 0.367 0.408 0.640 SERVED NUMBER OF 1.173* 0.939* 2.204* SMALL HUBS 0.221 0.195 0.529 SERVED AVERAGE STAGE -0.0278* -0.0135* -0.0506* LENGTH 0.0058 0.0058 0.0110 REVENUE PASSENGERS 0.00112* 0.00255* 0.000391 EMPLANEMENTS 0.00028 0.00037 0.000440 R-SQUARED 0.572 0.642 0.624 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.528 0.603 0.569 F-STATISTIC 13.041* 16.509* 11.460* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY TABLE 8-PART A 113 ABSOLUTE VARIABLES SECTION 2 - THREE-ENGINE REGULAR BODIED JETS DEPENDENT NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES VARIABLE 1963-1984 1963-1977 1978-1984 CONSTANT -5.080 -0.764 -33.0760* 6.617 5.118 15.395 NUMBER OF LARGE HUBS 1.302* 1.195* 2.396* SERVED 0.370 0.341 0.799 NUMBER OF MEDIUM HUBS -1.075* -l.467* 0.250 SERVED 0.315 0.328 0.620 NUMBER OF SMALL HUBS -0.799* -0.485* -l.585* SERVED 0.190 0.157 0.512 AVERAGE STAGE -0.00355 -0.00391 0.00690 LENGTH 0.00495 0.00463 0.01064 REVENUE PASSENGERS 0.00299* 0.00267* 0.00296* EMPLANEMENTS 0.00024 0.00030 0.00043 R-SQUARED 0.754 0.706 0.696 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.728 0.674 0.655 F—STATISTIC 29.889* 22.169* 16.027* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. TABLE 8-PART A SECTION 3 - FOUR-ENGINE REGULAR BODIED JETS 114 ABSOLUTE VARIABLES DEPENDENT NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES VARIABLE 1963-1984 1963-1977 1978-1984 CONSTANT -29.579* -25.828* -33.913* 7.478 8.0726 10.601 NUMBER OF LARGE HUBS 0.740 0.523 -0.142 SERVED 0.418 0.538 0.550 NUMBER OF 2.111* 1.133* 1.626* MEDIUM HUBS 0.356 0.517 0.427 SERVED NUMBER OF -0.393 -0.533* 0.0872 SMALL HUBS 0.215 0.247 0.353 SERVED AVERAGE STAGE -0.0639* -0.0689* -0.0455* LENGTH 0.0056 0.0073 0.0073 REVENUE PASSENGERS 0.000591* 0.00220* 9.801x10'5 EMPLANEMENTS 0.000275 0.00047 0.000293 R-SQUARED 0.668 0.729 0.550 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.634 0.700 0.485 F-STATISTIC 19.655* 24.828* 8.457* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. TABLE 8-PART A SECTION 4 - 115 ABSOLUTE VARIABLES THREE-ENGINE WIDE BODIED JETS DEPENDENT NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES VARIABLE 1970-1984 1970-1977 1978-1984 CONSTANT 1.602 -0.980 -l6.822* 2.722 4.272 5.765 NUMBER OF -0.212 -0.0254 0.235 LARGE HUBS 0.152 0.259 -0.299 SERVED NUMBER OF MEDIUM HUBS -0.419* -0.0644 -0.0818 SERVED 0.139 0.298 0.232 NUMBER OF SMALL HUBS -0.130 -0.423* 0.0413 SERVED 0.078 0.128 0.192 AVERAGE STAGE 0.00481* -0.00163 0.0200* LENGTH 0.00204 0.00298 0.0040 REVENUE PASSENGERS 0.00119* 0.00109* 0.00105* EMPLANEMENTS 9.992x10’5 0.00026 0.00016 R-SQUARED 0.722 0.626 0.713 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.694 0.575 0.672 F-STATISTIC 25.431* 12.331* 17.217* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY TABLE 8-PART A 116 ABSOLUTE VARIABLES SECTION 5 - four-engine WIDE BODIED JETS DEPENDENT NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES NUMBER OF PLANES VARIABLE 1963-1984 1970-1977 1978-1984 CONSTANT -8.022* -10.971* -23.254* 2.288 3.323 4.727 NUMBER OF LARGE HUBS 0.334* 0.542* 0.795* SERVED 0.128 0.201 0.255 NUMBER OF MEDIUM HUBS -0.606* -0.430 -0.804* SERVED 0.109 0.232 0.198 NUMBER OF SMALL HUBS 0.190* -0.0653 0.398* SERVED 0.066 0.0993 0.164 AVERAGE STAGE 0.0258* 0.0189* 0.0376* LENGTH 0.0017 0.0023 0.0034 REVENUE PASSENGERS 0.000105 0.000296 -3.676x10'S EMPLANEMENTS 8.4002(10”5 0.000199 0.000136 R-SQUARED 0.653 0.689 0.723 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.618 0.647 0.683 F-STATISTIC 18.396* 16.309* 18.903* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. 117 PART B TABLE 8-PART B RELATIVE VARIABLES SECTION 1 - Two-ENGINE REGULAR BODIED JETS DEPENDENT PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE OF PLANES OF PLANES OF PLANES VARIABLE 1963-1984 1963-1977 1978-1984 CONSTANT 0.520* 0.518* 0.683* 0.015 0.014 0.028 NUMBER OF LARGE HUBS -0.00349* -0.00406* -0.00485* SERVED 0.00082 0.00090 0.00148 NUMBER OF MEDIUM HUBS 0.00294* 0.00273* 0.00137 SERVED 0.00070 0.00087 0.00115 NUMBER OF SMALL HUBS 0.00124* 0.000931* 0.00259* SERVED 0.00042 0.000417 0.00095 AVERAGE STAGE -7.485x10** -4.164x10** -0.000129* IENGTH 1.100x10‘5 1.230x10’S 1.970x10'5 REVENUE PASSENGERS -1.384x10** -2.816x10‘7 -1.655x10** EMPLANEMENTS -5.397x10’7 --7.981xIO'7 1.970x10’7 R-SQUARED 0.490 0.484 0.619 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.437 0.428 0.563 F-STATISTIC 9.284* 8.554* 11.111* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 _13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY TABLE 8-PART B 118 RELATIVE VARIABLES SECTION 2 - THREE-ENGINE REGULAR BODIED JETS DEPENDENT PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE OF PLANES OF PLANES OF PLANES VARIABLE 1963-1984 1963-1977 1978-1984 CONSTANT 0.486* 0.495* 0.554* 0.0182 0.019 0.034 NUMBER OF LARGE HUBS 0.00464* 0.00570* 0.00342 SERVED 0.00101 0.00130 0.00178 NUMBER OF MEDIUM HUBS -0.00136 -0.00243* 0.000310 SERVED 0.00087 0.00125 0.00138 NUMBER OF SMALL HUBS -0.00162* -0.00155* -0.00278* SERVED 0.00052 0.00060 0.00114 AVERAGE STAGE -2.806x10'6 -1.962x10’5 1.6743(10’5 LENGTH 1.364x10'S 1.762x10‘5 2.366x10* REVENUE PASSENGERS 9.917x10"7 1.517x10‘6 1.136x10'E EMPLANEMENTS 6.690x10’6 1.143x10* 9.475x10’7 R-SQUARED 0.408 0.375 0.1807 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.347 0.307 0.0608 F-STATISTIC 6.653* 5.472* 1.507 NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. TABLE 8-PART B 119 RELATIVE VARIABLES SECTION 3 - four-engine REGULAR BODIED JETS DEPENDENT PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE OF PLANES OF PLANES OF PLANES VARIABLE 1963-1984 1963-1977 1976-1984 CONSTANT 0.474* 0.469* 0.466* 0.009 0.009 0.013 NUMBER OF LARGE HUBS 0.00244* 0.00358* 0.000210 SERVED 0.00048 0.00062 0.000665 NUMBER OF MEDIUM HUBS 0.00075 -0.00036 0.00143* SERVED 0.00041 0.00060 0.00052 NUMBER OF SMALL HUBS -0.000693* -0.00075* -0.000207 SERVED 0.000245 0.00029 0.000427 AVERAGE STAGE 7.592x10** 8.390x10** 6.086x10** LENGTH 6.3971(10'5 8.472x10‘ 8.8611(10’E REVENUE PASSENGERS 2.748x104’ 6.9321(10'7 5.438x10’a EMPLANEMENTS 3 . 139x10'7 5 . 497x10‘7 3 . 548x10'7 R-SQUARED 0.643 0.681 0.549 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.606 0.646 0.483 F-STATISTIC 17.356* 19.485* 8.305* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. STARRED STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE F-STATISTIC INDICATES COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY TABLE 8-PART B 120 RELATIVE VARIABLES SECTION 4 - THREE-ENGINE WIDE BODIED JETS DEPENDENT PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE OF PLANES OF PLANES OF PLANES VARIABLE 1970-1984 1970-1976 1977-1984 CONSTANT 0.520* 0.529* 0.529* 0.009 0.011 0.013 NUMBER OF LARGE HUBS -0.000360 -0.000731 5.960x10* SERVED 0.000469 0.000671 0.00068 NUMBER OF MEDIUM HUBS -0.00109* -0.000891 -0.00117* SERVED 0.00041 0.000782 0.00053 NUMBER OF SMALL HUBS -0.000539* -0.000712* -0.000456 SERVED 0.000266 0.000335 0.000434 AVERAGE STAGE -3.062x10“7 -1.027x10'5 1.285x10'5 LENGTH 5.820x10‘ 7.839x10’6 9.0173410”E REVENUE PASSENGERS 1.135x10** 1.356x10‘t 1.035x10** EMPLANEMENTS 3.039x104' R-SQUARED 0.289 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.208 F-STATISTIC 3.550* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 6.722x10‘7 0.249 0.144 2.375 185 19 3.611xIO’7 0.208 0.092 1.797 96 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY 121 TABLE 8-PART B RELATIVE VARIABLES SECTION 5 - FOUR-ENGINE WIDE BODIED JETS DEPENDENT PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE PERCENTAGE OF PLANES OF PLANES OF PLANES VARIABLE 1970-1984 1970-1976 1977-1984 CONSTANT 0.485* 0.505* 0.472* 0.009 0.012 0.011 NUMBER OF LARGE HUBS 0.00124* 0.000343 0.00195* SERVED 0.00045 0.000698 0.00056 NUMBER OF MEDIUM HUBS -0.00241* -0.00307* -0.00247* SERVED 0.00040 0.00081 0.00044 NUMBER OF SMALL HUBS 4.431x10‘5 -0.000302 0.000287 SERVED 2.563):10'4 0.000348 0.000361 AVERAGE STAGE 4.571x10** 2.858x10** 6.381x10** LENGTH 5.602x104 8.151x10* 7.4883(10'E REVENUE PASSENGERS 5.167x10‘7 1.781x10** 1.523x10'7 EMPLANEMENTS 2.922x10’7 6.9893(10‘7 2.9963(10'7 R-SQUARED 0.585 0.496 0.717 ADJ R-SQUARED 0.538 0.426 0.677 F-STATISTIC 12.404* 7.073* 17.560* NUMBER OF OBSERVATIONS 281 185 96 NUMBER OF REGRESSORS 27 19 13 STARRED COEFFICIENTS ARE SIGNIFICANTLY DIFFERENT FROM ZERO AT THE 5% LEVEL. STANDARD ERRORS OF THE COEFFICIENTS ARE REPORTED BELOW COEFFICIENT. STARRED F-STATISTIC INDICATES SIGNIFICANT AT 5% OR BETTER. COEFFICIENTS OF ANNUAL DUMMY VARIABLES NOT REPORTED. 122 aircraft. In the second section of this table, the dependent variable represented is the percentage of each of the aircraft types listed above in the various airline fleets. For this reason these tables are referred to as relative variables. These dependent variables were subjected to a logit transformation before the estimating equations were run. The coefficients of the annual dummies are not reported in table 8. In addition to the results reported for the entire sample period, estimates were made of the relationship between route characteristics and the number and type of aircraft employed for two sub-periods within the sample period. These sample periods were chosen on the basis of historical events which might have affected the relationships studied. The advent of airline deregulation in 1978 represents an obvious change in the operating environment of the airlines. The regression results reported in table 8 include full-period results for 1963- 1984 or 1970-1984, depending on the variety of aircraft, and 1963-1977 or 1970-1977 and 1978-1984 are the sub- periods. Of major interest in dealing with the sub-periods is the stability of the parameter values of the dependent variables. In order to determine this we perform the following test on the regressions. The null hypothesis is that there is no structural change over the full sample 123 period. In the test, the regression is run with and without an interacted variable, which takes the value of zero for the prederegulation period and the value of the independent variables for the period subsequent to deregulation. The test of the null hypothesis is an F test of the equality of the coefficients of the interacted variables and zero. The results of these test are reported in table 9. Theoretical Expectations The maintained hypothesis of this dissertation is that the effects of airline regulation were felt most strongly in the inefficient allocation of aircraft among markets and not in the initial choice of aircraft. Thus deregulation should witness an alteration in the relationship between route structure and the number of aircraft in airline fleets. However, if efficient mixes of aircraft for serving diverse markets were chosen by airlines prior to deregulation, these relationships should not have been altered subsequent to deregulation. The results reported above support this hypothesis. In the theoretical analysis of chapter 3, the number of aircraft an airline needs to serve its route network is a direct function of the number of flights per day scheduled on the network. The number of flights scheduled will in turn depend on the demand characteristics (i.e., passenger density or value of time) of each route served. 124 In the regressions conducted here, the average number of passengers per day emplaned at each of the three hub classes ( small, medium, and large ) are employed as proxies for the magnitude of the demand characteristics. The number of each class served also enters the regressions. The numbers of each of the five varieties of aircraft respond differently to changes in the numbers of passengers emplaned. In the case of the smallest varieties of aircraft, cost minimization considerations should result in fewer aircraft in the fleet, ceteris paribus, as the number of large hubs served increases. For small hubs the opposite should hold. Also, as the number of passengers served by an airline increases, fewer small aircraft should be used. The coefficients for these independent variables should be negative for two- and three-engine narrow-body jets. In other words, the same cost minimization considerations should lead to greater representation of these aircraft in fleets. Three- and four-engine wide-body jets, according to the same logic, will be the cost minimizing types for airlines which serve predominantly large hubs. Thus, for these aircraft, the expected sign of these independent variables is positive. Again, the reciprocal logic holds for small hubs for both average numbers of passengers and number served. The coefficients for these variables are expected to be negative. 125 TABLE 9 PANEL DATA RESULTS 1970-1984 The statistics reported here, distributed as F with the indicated degrees of freedom, were calculated from the data panel used in these regressions for the time period 1970-1984. The functional form estimated in the unrestricted regressions was: Dependent variable = Intercept +q Dependent variable + q Dependent variable * Dummy (=0 for observations before 1978, =1 for observations there after) '+'H dummy variables (=1 in year of the observation, =0 otherwise) The null hypothesis is m = 0 for all i. RELATIVE VARIABLES AIRCRAFT TYPE F-statistic (all Fs have 6&159 d.f) two-engine 2.6017465626* narrow-body three-engine 1.2991934175 narrow-body four-engine 5.6073423858* narrow-body three-engine 1.5800478791 wide-body four-engine 3.2185994789* wide-body 126 TABLE 9 (CONT) ABSOLUTE VARIABLES AIRCRAFT TYPE F-statistic (all Fs have 6&162 d.f) two-engine 5.5421539469* narrow-body three-engine 6.0238452157* narrow-body four-engine 4.3664467113* narrow-body three-engine 5.6120964069* wide-body four-engine 3.8286429632* wide-body STARRED F-STATISTICS INDICATE THE COMPUTED F EXCEEDS THE FIVE PERCENT LEVEL OF SIGNIFICANCE. 127 The intermediate cases ( i.e., four-engine narrow-body jets and number of passengers and number of medium hubs served ) have not yet been discussed. As might be expected, the signs for these variables cannot readily be predicted. The predictions made above apply equally to the absolute variables and to the relative variables estimated as dependent variables in the regressions. One further prediction can be ventured, based on the hypothesis discussed in the first paragraph of this section. The maintained hypothesis is that aircraft choices, but not utilization, are efficient. In the post-deregulation environment, the relationship between route structure and the relative shares of different aircraft in an airline’s fleet should not have changed significantly. On the other hand, given the joint product nature of airline flights where hubbing and spoking is employed, the number of flights and thus airline fleet requirements should have increased. Therefore, statistical tests of changes in the relationship of route characteristics to fleet composition should show a change for absolute variables and no such change for relative variables. The theoretical predictions and the signs resulting from the empirical estimates are reported in table 10. 128 TABLE 10 COMPARISONS OF THEORY AND EMPIRICAL RESULTS PART I Dependent variable is the average number of seats per flight for an airline in a year. INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN EXPECTED OBSERVED CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) (’76-'84) ('76—'84) LARGE HUB + MEDIUM HUB - SMALL HUB - PASSENGERS + (REVENUE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE STAGE + LENGTH ANNUAL <0 before 1970 DUMMIES >0 after 1970 INCREASED MAGNITUDE ? DECREASED ABSOLUTE VALUE INCREASED MAGNITUDE DECREASED MAGNITUDE NEGATIVE VALUES NONE INCREASED YES NOT SIGNIFICANT INCREASED 129 PART II Dependent variable is the number of aircraft of the given type in an airline fleet in a year. two-engine narrow-body (DC-9, B-737, MD-80) INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) (’76-’84) (’76-’84) LARGE HUB - - INCREASED YES ABSOLUTE VALUE MEDIUM HUB ? ? ? ? SMALL HUB + + INCREASED YES MAGNITUDE PASSENGERS - + INCREASED NO (REVENUE ABSOLUTE VALUE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE - - INCREASED YES STAGE ABSOLUTE VALUE LENGTH ANNUAL ? ACHIEVE DUMMIES POSITIVE SIGNIFICANCE 130 three-engine narrow-body (BOEING 727) INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) (’76-’84) (’76-’84) LARGE HUB - + INCREASED YES ABSOLUTE VALUE MEDIUM HUB ? - ? ? SMALL HUB + - DECREASED YES MAGNITUDE PASSENGERS + + INCREASED YES (REVENUE MAGNITUDE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE - ? DECREASED ? STAGE ABSOLUTE VALUE LENGTH ANNUAL ? ACHIEVE DUMMIES POSITIVE SIGNIFICANCE 131 four-engine narrow-body INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) ('76-’84) (’76-’84) LARGE HUB + +(?) ALL SIGNS MEDIUM HUB ? + AMBIGUOUS SMALL HUB - -(?) BECAUSE OF PASSENGERS + + (REVENUE OBSOLESCENCE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE - - STAGE LENGTH ANNUAL POSITIVE DUMMIES BUT DECLINING 132 three-engine wide-body INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) (’76-’84) (’76-’84) LARGE HUB + ? INCREASED YES MAGNITUDE MEDIUM HUB (-)? -(?) INCREASED NO ABSOLUTE VALUE SMALL HUB - - INCREASED ? ABSOLUTE VALUE PASSENGERS + + INCREASED NO (REVENUE MAGNITUDE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE STAGE + + INCREASED NO LENGTH MAGNITUDE ANNUAL =0 1963-1971 DECREASED DUMMIES >0 1971-1984 MAGNITUDE 133 four-engine wide-body INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) (’76-’84) (’76-’84) LARGE HUB + + INCREASED YES MAGNITUDE MEDIUM HUB - INCREASED YES ABSOLUTE VALUE SMALL HUB -(?) + INCREASED YES ABSOLUTE VALUE PASSENGERS + ? INCREASED ? (REVENUE MAGNITUDE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE + + INCREASED YES STAGE MAGNITUDE LENGTH ANNUAL =0 BEFORE 1970 NO SIGNIFICANT DUMMIES >0 AFTER 1970 DIFFERENCE PART III Dependent variable is the percentage of aircraft of the given type in an airline fleet in a year. two-engine narrow-body INDEPENDENT PREDICTED VARIABLE (FULL PERIOD) LARGE HUB MEDIUM HUB SMALL HUB PASSENGERS (REVENUE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE STAGE LENGTH ANNUAL DUMMIES OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (’76-'84) ('76-’84) INCREASED YES ABSOLUTE VALUE ? ? INCREASED YES MAGNITUDE INCREASED YES ABSOLUTE VALUE INCREASED YES ABSOLUTE VALUE SIGNIFICANTLY POSITIVE 135 three-engine narrow-body INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) (’76-’84) (’76-’84) LARGE HUB + + INCREASED ? MAGNITUDE MEDIUM HUB + ? INCREASED +(?) MAGNITUDE SMALL HUB - - INCREASED YES ABSOLUTE VALUE PASSENGERS + 2 INCREASED ? (REVENUE MAGNITUDE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE - ? DECREASED ? STAGE ABSOLUTE VALUE LENGTH ANNUAL + SIGNIFICANTLY DUMMIES POSITIVE 136 four-engine narrow-body INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) (’76-’84) (’76-’84) LARGE HUB - AIRCRAFT TYPE MEDIUM HUB - OBSOLETE IN SMALL HUB — LATE 19703 PASSENGERS + (REVENUE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE + STAGE LENGTH ANNUAL POSITIVE DUMMIES BUT DIMINISHING 137 three-engine wide-body INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) ('76-'84) (’76-'84) LARGE HUB + ? INCREASED ? MAGNITUDE MEDIUM HUB - - INCREASED ? ABSOLUTE VALUE SMALL HUB - - INCREASED ? ABSOLUTE VALUE PASSENGERS + + INCREASED NONE (REVENUE MAGNITUDE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE + ? INCREASED ? STAGE MAGNITUDE LENGTH ANNUAL =0 BEFORE 1971 SIGNIFICANTLY DUMMIES >0 AFTER 1971 DIFFERENT FROM REGULATION 138 four-engine wide-body INDEPENDENT PREDICTED OBSERVED EXPECTED OBSERVED VARIABLE SIGN SIGN CHANGE CHANGE (FULL PERIOD) (FULL PERIOD) (’76-'84) (’76-'84) LARGE HUB + + INCREASED YES MAGNITUDE MEDIUM HUB - - INCREASED NO ABSOLUTE VALUE SMALL HUB - ? INCREASED ? ABSOLUTE VALUE PASSENGERS + ? INCREASED ? (REVENUE MAGNITUDE PASSENGER EMPLANEMENTS) AVERAGE + + INCREASED YES STAGE MAGNITUDE LENGTH ANNUAL =0 BEFORE 1970 SIGNIFICANTLY DUMMIES >0 AFTER 1970 DIFFERENT 139 Analysis of Empirical Results The predictions ventured in the previous section were only partly correct, as can be established by consulting table 10. For two-engine narrow-body aircraft, the signs of the coefficients for large and small hubs and passengers per day emplaned at each are as predicted for both the full sample and the sub-periods. They are also significantly different from zero in almost all equations, whether the dependent variable is number of aircraft or of an aircraft type in a fleet. The coefficients for medium hubs are seldom significant and, as predicted, of varying sign. The predictions regarding the signs of the coefficients in the equations for three-engine narrow-body jets are almost completely wrong. The number of large hubs and the average number of passengers per day at large hubs have significant,' positive coefficients. The coefficient of the average number of passengers per day served at small hubs is insignificantly different from zero in all equations. The coefficient of the number of small hubs is negative where significantly different from zero. Four-engine narrow-body jets, for which no prediction was ventured, have the same pattern of sign and significance as was predicted for larger jets. 140 For wide-bodied aircraft, the predictions are largely confirmed. The coefficients on the large hub variables are uniformly positive and generally significant. The coefficients of the small hub variables are negative but seldom significant. The medium-hub variables are negative and usually significant. These results are quite striking. Finally, the change of regimes test reported in table 9 yields some striking results. For the regressions where the dependent variable is the numbers of aircraft of each type employed by the carriers during the period, the tests indicate that the relationship between route characteristics and number of aircraft selected of a given type changed in a statistically significant fashion. In those regressions where the dependent variable is the percentage of aircraft of a given type in the airlines fleet, application of the same structural tests yields results that are different. In fact, these tests indicate that the relationship of the relative composition of airlines' fleets to their routes did not change for three- engine narrow-body and three-engine wide-body jets subsequent to deregulation. In other words, airline fleets tended to contain about the same proportions of three-engine jets after deregulation. This finding is at variance with predictions that would have been made about the airline fleets on the basis of the economic analysis of airlines prior to deregulation. However, three varieties of aircraft show changed relationships between aircraft 141 fleet proportions and route characteristics. In the case of four-engine narrow-body aircraft this finding can be explained by the technological obsolescence of the class. In the case of two-engine narrow-body aircraft, the utilization of these craft on lower density spokes may in fact mean that they are needed in increased proportions since deregulation. Since flight frequency was identified as the prime competitive weapon under regulatory constraint, airlines would have been expected to have fleets with small aircraft over-represented relative to large aircraft. This is not reflected in the empirical results. In fact, these results support the thesis of this dissertation that the major effects of airline deregulation on airline allocation of capital have not been upon the choice of aircraft in general but on the route structures within which the aircraft are employed. Summary of Empirical Results In summary, these regressions indicate that the model presented in chapter 3 has significant explanatory power. The changes in aircraft utilization patterns in the period from 1974 to 1984 clearly reflects the effects of deregulation. In particular the restructuring of airline networks into hub-and-spoke systems is reflected. In the post-deregulation scheme of things, wide-bodied aircraft are used predominantly for long-haul, inter-hub 142 transfers. The smaller aircraft are used to carry passengers on the spokes where passenger densities are lowest. All other things equal, as passenger densities and/or route distance increase, three-engine jets (i.e. Boeing 727) displace smaller varieties of aircraft on the spokes. Such aircraft are also employed on the less dense inter-hub flights (e.g., Chicago to Charlotte, N.C.). CHAPTER 5 CONCLUSION AND SUGGESTIONS FOR FURTHER RESEARCH This dissertation has been concerned with some elements of the structure of the airline industry which make it unique. These idiosyncratic features result in industry conduct and performance not easily explained within the framework of conventional models of economic behavior. An alternative analytical framework was provided above. This framework was then tested empirically using two distinct data sets. These empirical results were largely consistent with the predictions of the model developed here. This chapter reviews the unique elements of the airline industry’ s structure, the predictions of deregulated industry performance, and the specific shortcomings of these a priori models. These models are then compared with the superior predictive performance of the alternative model developed here. Finally, the empirical tests of the model are reviewed and conclusions 143 144 drawn from the results advanced. In addition, some possible empirical and theoretical extensions of this investigation are suggested. The srrgcture of the Industry As outlined in chapter I, the passenger airline industry has a number of unique structural elements which make it both rewarding and difficult to analyze economically. An important feature throughout the first half century of the industry's history was pervasive regulation. of’ price and route entry. Since the late 1970s, much of the behavior of airlines has taken the form of adjustment to the changes caused by elimination of the price and entry regulation of the industry. Two related elements of the industry structure also help to make it unique. The first is the nature of its product. The "product" of the airline industry consists of point-to-point transportation offered at a particular time of day. Any product is one of a class of related products, each consisting of a flight between the same two points but originating at a different time of day. This is true Ibecause the. opportunity cost of air transport is not merely the cash price paid for such transport but also the opportunity cost of time of travel. Travel time itself includes several elements including the 145 actual point-to-point time, the delay occasioned by flights not departing at the preferred time, and delays caused by not being able to take a preferred flight because it is full. Of these, only the first--the point-to-point transit time-~is truly exogenous in the short run. It is determined by the the technological characteristics of the aircraft available. Aircraft availability is the second element of the structure of airline transportation that makes the airline industry unique. Because of the lumpiness of airline capital-—that is, aircraft--airlines are faced with a choice of several varieties of aircraft. The lumpiness of airline capital makes it impossible for airlines to offer custom-tailored "products." Instead airlines :must offer' products ‘which. provide lowest opportunity cost of air travel. The combination of these three elements before deregulation resulted in a voluminous literature about the industry structure. This body of theoretical and empirical literature will be discussed next. co O ' 'n 5 Two empirical observations were seminal in the analysis of airline performance under CAB regulation. First, it was recognized that, despite fares set above 146 competitive levels and the protection from competitive pressures provided by CAB entry restrictions, airlines did not earn economic profits. Indeed, they frequently earned no 'profits at all. In addition, observation of less regulated intrastate carriers in California and Texas revealed that these carriers were able to earn profits with lower fares than CAB-regulated carriers. This was caused by the substantially lower costs of the intrastate carriers. Providing an explanation of these observations consistent with profit maximizing behavior was an important challenge of the economic literature of the early 19705. The key element in the explanation eventually adopted was the nature of the opportunity costs faced by air travelers and the absence of price competition in the airline industry. Since airlines could not freely compete in price of service, they competed on the other element of air travelers' cost of air travel: travel time. Specifically, competition took the form of offering increased flight frequency, a competitive variable not subject to regulation. This had the effect of increasing airline average costs, since fewer passengers were carried on each individual flight, thereby increasing the per-passenger share of flight costs which are fixed once the route and type of aircraft employed are determined. This theory provided the basis for a series of 147 predictions regarding airline behavior subsequent to removal of regulation. With airlines free to compete on price of service, it was predicted that flight frequency would fall and airlines would increase their utilization of larger aircraft. There were two hidden weaknesses of this theory, however. First, it was generally assumed that airlines would not substantially alter their route structures except to expand them. A second assumption was that airlines would charge a single fare for any particular class of service after receiving pricing freedom. Both of these assumptions proved false after deregulation. The consequences of this are considered in the next section. W The third chapter presents a theoretical framework for understanding the responses of airlines to deregulation. Its basis is a model of how airlines might determine flight frequency in particular markets, and is an extension of work by Steven Salop (1984). The model forms the building block upon which an understanding of the principles of airline fleet selection can be constructed. An important extension of Salop's model is one utilized to explain the practice of hub-and-spoke networks. In this framework, hub-and-spoke networking can be interpreted as a problem of joint production. In addition, 148 a form of price discrimination, where customers are distinguished by both their differing destinations and differing opportunity cost of time, is illustrated. As is common in joint production and price discrimination models, the result is higher levels of provision of the good. The ability to spread the fixed costs of production across several different classes of consumers yields these increases in production. This leads to the conclusion that the effect of the adoption of hubbing and spoking on airline flight frequencies is to increase flight frequency from an origin, ggrgr1§__pgribg§. This conclusion is contrary to the expectations held before deregulation but is a natural consequence of the model employed. This result is a generalization of the result of Morrison and Winston discussed above(1984). In this model, the decision to hub and spoke involves balancing revenue losses caused by decreased convenience of service with the lowered costs of joint production. Airlines are the only passenger transportation mode where the cost savings in both cash and time are generally enough to offset the increased time cost of not proceeding directly to a destination. There is some evidence that for surface freight transportation, particularly less than truckload shipment, can enjoy economies with a network of the hub- and-spoke variety. In general, the theoretical results derived in the 149 third chapter point to a very different interpretation of the consequences of deregulation than was previously held. In particular, the model of this dissertation indicates that a) deregulation should lead to increased flight frequencies as airlines adjust their networks to the more efficient hub-and-spoke structure, and b) the requirements of frequency of service imply that smaller aircraft will not be displaced by larger aircraft as was predicted in previous models. m 1 cal od 5 ' avio The fourth chapter of this dissertation presented tests of its theoretical framework. Two distinct sets of data are used. In the first set, the airlines behavior at the level of individual routes is investigated. The number of aircraft of different types employed is the dependent variable regressed against the route characteristics of a randomly chosen set of American airline routes for two years, 1974 and 1984. In another set of regressions the average number of seats per flight on a route is employed as the dependent variable. The results tend to provide confirmation for the theory constructed here. There was a clear movement towards employing aircraft whose characteristics make them especially suitable for the "spokes" of a hub-and-spoke network. 150 In the second set of regressions, the gross fleet composition of major airlines is regressed against the route characteristics of those airlines. This is done in three ways. The first utilizes the absolute numbers of each of several aircraft types. In the second the relative frequency of different aircraft varieties is the dependent variable in the regressions. Additionally, the average number seats in the airline's fleet is employed as the dependent variable. These regressions confirm some of the theoretical predictions about airline fleet composition. The regression employing absolute fleet numbers as dependent variable indicates both that the relationship between route characteristics and fleet composition changed with deregulation and that the direction of the change is toward larger numbers of aircraft in fleets. In the regressions employing relative fleet composition, there is less indication of a changed relationship between the route structures of airlines and the relative proportions of different types of aircraft in their fleets. In particular, the early prediction that smaller jets would disappear with service competition in terms of flight frequency was never borne out. 151 -re _m‘, 1 "'1‘ '11.. -°"_: ’I O 13!. .133 What implications may be drawn from the results of this research? One is that regulation did not necessarily induce airlines to make inefficient choices of aircraft. Instead, the inefficiencies were generated through the airline's inability to create efficient route structures while subject to entry regulation. Thus far this dissertation has not directly discussed the welfare implications of airline deregulation. Implicitly, the argument of the previous paragraph is that the welfare consequences of regulation were less significant than previously believed. A further statement about the welfare consequences of deregulation can in fact be made. Salop's model (1978), which forms the basis for the theoretical model of this dissertation, also permits the evaluation. of social welfare in. a :monopolistically competitive industry. This welfare evaluation indicates that the number of varieties of the good offered will be excessive from a social point of view. The model of Panzar (1979) is specifically intended to evaluate the behavior of the deregulated airline industry. It also suggests that airlines will offer more than the socially optimal number of flights. The theory of hubbing and spoking developed 152 here implies that an even greater number of flights will be offered than is indicated by the simple, monopolistically competitive models. Thus, it is a likely consequence of deregulation that an excessive number of flights will be offered. The relatively weak welfare results presented by the authors cited can be considered strengthened. In addition, the mathematical similarity of the hub- and-spoke model presented here to the price discrimination results also presented in chapter 3 indicates that the distributional consequences of deregulation have been insufficiently considered. In fact, this model provides an alternative to Levine’s (1987) explanation of how the incumbent airlines with significantly higher costs were able to prevail in competition with lower cost, new entrants. Their ability to earn rents through the hub—and- spoke system and the advantages conferred by their more extensive route systems in hubbing and spoking surely contribute to their succeSs. Thus, despite the significant benefits of deregulation, the picture is perhaps not so rosy as its proponents would have it. Air carriers continue to earn some rents in the deregulated environment. At least three possibilities for building on this work present themselves. In the case of the empirical results reported here, two useful extensions might be made. First, the route level results reported here might be duplicated with another sample to confirm the results reported. A 153 second step would be to find a superior proxy for the opportunity cost of air traveler's time. Per capita income was seldom statistically significant, despite strong theoretical expectations, regarding' income's role in determining' the cost. of time and its implications for flight scheduling. On a theoretical level, the assumption that the population of potential airline travelers is uniformly distributed throughout the course of a day is used here and elsewhere for want of an alternative. The problem of rivalrous airline scheduling where demand assymetries exist is worthy of attention, on both theoretical and empirical grounds. Appendix A Data Types and Sources As discussed in chapter 3, an airline’s demand for aircraft can be explained in terms of the demand characteristics of the markets served and the economic and regulatory environment. The variables presented in the theory (are not represented exactly by any data sources readily available. In order to perform econometric estimates proxies must be found for four distinct varieties of variables. The first is aircraft types. Two distinct sources of data were consulted to develop models of aircraft utilization. The aircraft data for the route level estimates presented in chapter 3 comes from the July 1974 and July 1984 editions of The Offigial Airline Guidel North American Edition. A random sample of domestic airlines' routes was constructed from these editions of the guide and utilized to construct statistics on the utilization of various types of aircraft on those routes. In addition, the hubbing variable was constructed by assigning a value of one to all routes listed as providing connecting flights on the sampled route. 154 155 Population and per capita income variables were constructed by using either The Stare and Metropolitan Data @3433, 1986 edition, The Citvfiand Countv Data Book, 1977 edition, or the Rand-McNallv Commercial Atlae, 1986 edition. For“ route terminals (i.e. either’ origins or destinations) which were elements of Standard Metropolitan Statistical areas, the population and per capita income of the SMSA was utilized. For terminals which were not so classified, the population and per capita income of the surrounding county was employed. The route distance variable was also derived form multiple sources. For many major cities, the 1974 edition of the OAG provided a table of domestic airline mileages, routes not listed in this source were taken from either foieel Table ef Distances, Continental U.S.ll Alaska, Hawaii, and Puerto Rico, Direct Line Distances, U.S. Editiog, or as a last resort nd-McNall Standard Hi Mileage Guide. The final variable in the route level regressions was the vacation variable. The vacation spot dummy was created by assigning a value of one to all routes with a terminal in Florida, Hawaii, coastal California, or the desert Southwest (i.e., Nevada, Arizona, and. New’ Mexico.) A continuous vacation variable was the per capita expenditures on lodging at either the origin or destination. The source of these continuous variables was 156 either The Statistical Abetracr or gounty Business Patterne both published by the U.S. Census Bureau. For the second set of regressions the primary source of data was The Handbook of Airline Statietice, published biannually between 1963 and 1973, with a supplement published for the years 1974 and 1975. This data source was supplemented for years after 1976 by The Inventory and Age of Aircraft Trunks d Loc ls, prepared by the Office of Economic Analysis of the CAB and the Air Transport Association’s Annual Reporr for 1983 and 1984. In these data sources different models of aircraft were classified according to their body style (i.e., either narrow-bodied or wide-bodied.) In addition, aircraft are classified by type and number of engines. These data were collected for the period 1963-1984 and consisted of the inventory of each of the CAB-defined types of aircraft in carrier fleets as Of December 31 of a given year. The initial year chosen was 1963 to minimize the disturbance to airline fleet composition consequent to the introduction of jet aircraft in the late 19503 (c.f. Yance, QRE_£il)- Nineteen eighty— four 'was chosen as an upper' bound by limits in data availability and the necessity to have sufficient sample years subsequent to deregulation. Since no single data source reported all years, the carrier fleet series were constructed only for carriers still existing and defined as "majors" in 1984. Where a merger had resulted in the 157 creation of a new "major ," the fleets and other statistics were combined for the entire sample period. The descriptive statistics used to characterize the route structure of the carriers were constructed from Airport Activity Statistics of Certificated Route Carriers reported annually for the years 1963-1984. In using this data, the conventions of the FAA in classifying airports as large,medium, and small hubs and as non-hubs depending on the percentage of U.S. airline passenger emplanements, was adopted.1 Adrline route structures were characterized by the numbers of each hub classification that they served and the average number of passengers served per day in each of these classifications. An additional variable used in the two stage least squares estimates of chapter 4 was the average stage length of airlines. This was reported in The Handbook of Airline Steeristics before 1976 and in Air Carrier Traffic firerieriee, also published by the CAB beginning in 1976. Each set of regressions reported below has a distinct source of data. Thus two independent tests of the hypothesis are provided by these results. 1 Large hubs have more than 1% of US passenger emplanements. Medium hubs have between 0.99% and 0.50% of U.S. passenger emplanements. Small hubs have between 0.49% and 0.25% of emplanements. Non-hubs emplane fewer than 0.25% of U.S. airline passengers. BIBLIOGRAPHY Air Transport Association, 1983. Annual Report, Washington, D.C. Air Transport Association, 1984. Apnual Report, Washington, D.C. Andrews, John, 1985, June 1. "Eternal Triangles," EGQEQEisf. 81-824- Bailey, Elizabeth E., and William Baumol, 1984. "Deregulation and the Theory of Contestable Markets," gale Journal on Begplation 1: 111-137. Bailey, Elizabeth E., David R. Graham, and Daniel P. Kaplan, 1985. Qeregplgrlpg fine Airlines, Cambridge, Mass. : MIT Press Boyer, Kenneth, 1984. "Is There a Principle for Defining Industries?". §nghern_negnemi2_lggrnal 50:761-770. Caves, Douglas W., Laurits R.Christensen, and Micheal W. Tretheway, 1984. "Economies of Density Versus Economies of Scale - Why Trunk and Local-Service Airline Costs Differ," Rene gournal of Economics 15:471-489. 158 159 De Vany, Arthur S., 1974. "The Revealed value Of Time in Air Travel," Beyiew e: Ecepomics epg Statistics 56:77- 82. Douglas, George W. and James C. Miller, 1974. Economic Regulation of Domestic Air Transport: Theory and Policy, Washington, D.C.:The Brookings Institute. Fitzpatrick, Gary L., and Marilyn J. Modlin, 1986. Direct Line Distances. U.S. Edition, Metuchen, N.J.: Scarecrow Press, Inc. Fomby, Thomas B., R. Carter Hill, and Stanley R. Johnson, 1984. Advanced Econometric Metgees, New York: Springer-Verlag Graham, David R., Daniel P. Kaplan, and David S. Sibley, 1983. "Efficiency and Competition in the Airline Industry." Egll_Jgurnal_2f_Eggngmigs 14:118-138. James, George W., 1982. Airli e Economics, Lexington Mass.: Lexington Books. Levine, Michael E., 1987. "Airline Competition in Deregulated Markets: Theory, Firm Strategy, and Public Policy." Ya12.192rnal_2n_negulafign 4:393-497. Morrison, Stephen. .A., and. Clifford. ‘Winston, 1985. " Intercity Transportation Route Structures under Deregulation: Some Assessments Motivated by the Airline Experience," Amerieen EeopepTc Review 75:57-61 Official Airline Guides, 1974, July 1. The Offleial Airline QEide1_E2rfh_AmeriGan_Edifien. Oakbrook. IL- Official Airline Guides, 1984, July 1. TAe foicial Airline QEide1_Eerfn_American_Edifign. Oakbrook. IL- Oster, Clinton V., and Don H. Pickrell, 1986. "Marketing Alliances and Competitive Strategy in the Airline Industry," Lpgl'sries epd Trepsportation Review 22:371-388. 160 Panzar, John, 1979. "Equilibrium and Welfare in Unregulated Alrllne Markets," AE_£i§2fl_§EQDQEiQ_B§!i§E 59: 92' 95- Peyrelevade, J., 1976. "Methodology For Determining Optimum Aircraft Fleets," Paris:Institut Du Transport Aerien. Pollack, Maurice, 1977. "Some Elements of the Airline Fleet Planning Problem," Transportatiep Research 11(5):301- 310. Rand-McNally, 1984. and-McNal Standa d Hi hwa Milea e Guide, Chicago, IL. --—, 1986. Rand-McNelly Qommerelel Atlas, Chicago, IL. Salop, Stephen, 1978. "Monopolistic Competition with Outside Goods," Bell Jeurpel of Eeopomles 10:141-156. Thomchick, E.C., 1978. "Long Term Effects of Airline Deregulation on the Domestic Route System and the Airline Industry," Ph.D. Dissertation, Clemson University, United States Bureau of Census. 1987. The Statietical Abstract of the United spates, Washington, D.C. ---. 1975. County Business Patterns Washington, D.C. ---. 1985. goupty Business Parterns Washington, D.C. —--. 1986. The State and Metro olit n Data Book, Washington, D.C. ---. 1977. The City and Qeunry Data Boo; Washington, D.C. Civil Aeronautics Board, 1964-1976. The Handbook of Airline Speristlcs, Washington, D.C. 161 ---. Office of Economic Analysis, 1977-1982. The Inventory and Age of Aircraft, Trunks and Locals, Washington, D.C. ---. 1976-1984. Air Carrier Traffic Statistics , Washington, D.C. U.S. Department of Defense, 1973. The Official Table of Distances. Continental U,S.. Alaskal Hawaii, and Buerto Rieo Washington, D.C.: Department of Army, Navy, and Air Force U.S. Federal Aviation Administration, 1963-1984. Airport Activitv Statistics of Certificated Route Carriers, Washington, D.C. Verleger, Phillip K., 1972. "Models of the Demand for Air Transportation," Bell Jourpal e: Economics, 2:437-457. Winston, Clifford, 1985. "Conceptual Developments in the Economics of Transportation: An Interpretative Survey," Jourpal pf Ecopomic Literature 23(2)57-94. Wyckoff, D. Daryl, and David H. Maister, 1977. The Domestic A1rl1pe_1pdge§ry, Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books. 162 GENERAL REFERENCES Adams, Walter, and James W.Brock, 1986. The Bigness Complex: IndustryI Laber. ape government in the American Economy, New York: Pantheon Books. Agarwal, Vinod, and Wayne K. Talley, 1978. "The Demand for International Air Passenger Service Provided by U.S. Air Carriers," International Journal of Transport Economics, 12(1):135-143. Anderson, James E., and Marvin Kraus, 1981. "Quality of Service and the Demand for Air Travel," Review of Economics and Statisrics, 63:533-540. Bailey, Elizabeth E., 1986. "Deregulation: Causes and Consequences," geiepee 234:1211-1216. Bailey, Elizabeth E., 1985. "Airline Deregulation in the U.S.: the Benefits Provided and Lessons Learned," Internar i onal gegrnel pf Transport Economics 12(1):119-144. Bailey, Elizabeth E., and John Panzar, 1981. "The Contestability of Airline Markets During the Transition to Deregulation,” Leg and Contemporary Problems 44:125-145. 163 Bauer, Paul W., 1987, 4th quarter. "Airline Hubs: A Study of Determining Factors and Effects", Economic Review ef The Federal Beserrye Bank of Cleveland, 13-19. Ben-Akiva, Moshe, and Steven R. Lerman, 1985. Discrete Choice Analysis: Theory and Application to Travel Demand, Cambridge, Mass.:MIT Press Bennet, Randall W., 1984. Qualitv of Service in Nonmonopoly Air Travel Markete: An Empirical Investigation. of Alternative Measures of Quality, Ph.D. Dissertation, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI. Bluestone, Barry, Peter Jordan, and Mark Sullivan, 1981. Aircraft lndustry Qynamics: An Analysis of Competition. Capital and Labor, Boston: Auburn House Publishing Company. Brown, Anthony, 1985. "The Regulatory Policy Cycle and the Airline Deregulation Movement," Social Science Quarterly 66:552-563. Brueckner, Jan R., 1985. "A Note on the Determinants of Metropolitan Airline Traffic," lnternatienel Journal of Transport Economice 12(2):175-184. Bruning, Edward R., and Larry E. Oberdick, 1982. "Market- Structure and Economic-Performance in the Commuter Airline Industry," TIQDERQILQEIQD Journal 21(3):?6-87. Call, Gregory D., and Theodore E. Keeler, 1985. "Airline Deregulation, Fares, and Market Behavior: Some Evidence," in Analyticel Spugies in Transport Eeongmics, ed. Andrew F. Daugherty, 221-247, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Cates, D. Brooks, 1978. ”Short-run Structural-Change in an Airline Network of Declining Connectivity," MW 30(1)=9-13- 164 Carlton, Dennis ‘W., William. M. Landes, and. Richard. A. Posner, 1980. "Benefits and Costs of Airline Mergers: A Case Study," Bell Qonrnel ef Economics 11:65-83. Caves, Douglas W., Laurits R. Christensen, and Michael W. Trethway, 1983. "Productivity Performance of U.S. Trunk and Local Service Airlines in the Era of Deregulation," Economic Ingniry 23:312-324. Caves, Douglas W., Laurits R. Christensen, and Michael W. Trethway , 1985 , "The Effect of New Entry on Productivity Growth in the U.S. Airline Industry: 1947-1981," Logisties and Transportation Review 21(4):297-335. Cooper, Michael H., and Alan K. Maynard, 1971, The Price of Air Travel, London: Institute of Economic Affairs. Cunningham, Lawrence F., Kenneth C. Williamson, and Wallace R. Wood, 1984, "Planning Decisions in Commuter Airlines." Transnertafien_122rnal 23(3)=53-62. Davis, Grant M. and John E.Dillard, Jr., 1984. "The Professional Traveler and The Airline Deregulation Act of 1978: An Appraisal," Treneportation Research Forum: Proceedings or the Tyenry-gnird Annual Meeting 23(1):419-426. De Vany, Arthur S., 1975. "The Effect of Price and Entry Regulation on Airline Output, Capacity , Efficiency," Bell_229rnal_9f_figgngmi2§ 6(1): 327-345- Dorman, Gary Jay, 1983. "A Model of Unregulated Airline Markets," Besearen in Trensperpapion Ecenomics 1:131- 148. Ellison, Anthony P., 1982. "The Structural Change of the Airline Industry Following Deregulation," Tranengrtafign_iggrnal 21(3)=58-69- 165 Eriksen, Steven E., and Nawal K. Taneja, 1980. "Evaluation of Scheduled Air Passenger Service in Domestic Markets," Journal of Airereft 17(1):53-57. Fisher, Franklin M., 1988. "Pan Am to United: The Pacific Division Transfer Case," The Rand Journal Of Economics 18(4):492-508. Formby, John P., James P. Keeler, and Paul D. Thistle, 1986. " Cost Differentials Under Regulation: The Case of U.S. Passenger Airlines," Unpublished paper presented at the Southern Economics Association Meetings, November 25, 1986. Gaynor, M., and John Trapani, 1986. "An Hedonic Approach to Assessing the Welfare Effects of U.S. Airline Deregulation," Unpublished paper presented at the meetings of the Southern Economics Association, November 25,1986. Gillen, David W., Tae H. Oum, and Micheal W. Tretheway, 1985. Airline Cost and Performance: lmplications for Enblic and Industry Policy Vancouver, Canada:Centre for Transportation Studies, University of British Columbia. Gomez-Ibanez, Jose, Clinton V. Oster, and Don H. Pickrell, 1983. "Airline Deregulation: What’s Behind the Recent Losses?", Journal pf Poliey Anelyeie eng Managemenp 3:74-89. Governor’s Air Service Task Force, date unknown, Recommendatione fer Mienigan's Air Service lmprovements, Lansing, MI: Governor's Air Service Task Force. Hale, Francis J., 1984. troduc o to Aircraft W. New York: John Wiley and Sons. 166 Hunsaker, James, 1984. "The Domestic 30 to 60 Seat Commuter Aircraft Market: A Supply and Demand Analysis," a o tat'o s o m° o ee n s of the Tyenty-third Annual Meeting 23(1):427-433. Ippolito, Richard A., 1981. "Estimating Airline Demand with Quality of Service Variables," Journal of Traneport Economics and Policy 15(1):7-15. Johnson, Richard L., 1985. "Networking and Market Entry in the Airline Industry," lonrnel or Transport Economics end Policy 19:299-304. Jones, Ronald W., 1965. "The Structure of Simple General Equilibrium Models," Tne Qenrnel e: Political Economy 73(6):557-572. Jordan, William A., 1970. Airline Begnlarien in America, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press. Jordan, William A., 1986. "Results of U.S. Airline Deregulation: Evidence from ‘the Regulated Canadian Airlines," 5 o i ev' w 22(4):297-338. Jung, J.M., and E.T. Fujii, 1976. "The Price Elasticity of Demand for Air Travel," leurnal pf Transport Economics end Poliey 10:257-262. Keeler, Theodore, 1981. "The Revolution in Airline Regulation," in Qase Srugiee in Pegnlerien; Revolurion eng_3efierny eds. Leonard Weiss and M. Klass, Boston: Little, Brown and Company. Keeler, Theodore, and Micheal Abrahams, 1981. "Market Structure, Pricing, and Service Quality in the Airline Industry under Deregulation," in Applieariens pf o c' s bl c ilities, Industries, eds. Werner Sichel and Thomas Gies, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 167 La Mond, Annette M., 1976. "An Evaluation of Intrastate Airline Regulation in California," e Jour a o Economige 7:641-657. Leonard, William N., 1983. "Airline Deregulation: Grand Design or Gross Debacle? ”, genrnal 0: Economic Iesuee 7:453-462. MacAvoy, Paul W., and John W.Snow, 1977. Regulation of Passenger Fares ene Qomperition Among Airlines, Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute. Mandall, Robert W., 1979 Pineneing The Capital Regnirements of the U.S. Airline Industry in the 19805, Lexington, Mass: Lexington Books. Mannering, Fred L., and Clifford Winston, 1985. "A Dynamical Empirical Analysis of Household Vehicle Ownership and Utilization," Band Jenrnal of Economics 16(2):215-236. Mayer, Jonathan D., 1977. "Local and Commuter Airlines in United States," Traffiie Quarterly 31(2):333-349. Meyer, John R., and Clinton V. Oster, eds., 1981. Airline Deregulation; The Eerly Experienee, Boston, Mass: Auburn House Publishing Company. Meyer, John R., and Clinton V. Oster, eds., 1984. DeregBlafi2n__juEL__fhe__lEaL__Airline__1uuarzuzauayg5. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press. Miller, James C., 1982. "Time of Day Modeling for Aircraft Scheduling." Transnertati9n_§ciense 6:221-246- Molloy, J.F., 1985. The Qennnrer Airline lndusrry: Policy Algerneriyee, Lexington, Mass: Lexington Books. 168 Moore, Thomas Gale, 1986. "U.S. Airline Deregulation: It’s Effects on Passengers, Capital, and Labor," The Journal 0; Law ane Economics 29(1):l-28. Morrel, Peter S., and. Nawal K; Taneja, 1979. "Airline Productivity Redefined - Analysis of United States and European Carriers," Trensporrarion 8(1):37-49. Morrison, Stephen, and Clifford Winston, 1986. The Eeonomic Egfiects pf Airline Qeregnlerien, Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institute. Newhouse, John, 1982. The Sporry Gene, New York: Alfred A. Knopf. O'Connor, William E., 1978. ct' t Airl'ne Economics, New York: Praeger Publishers. O'Connor, William E., 1985. An Introduction to Airline Economiesl 3re ee,, New York: Praeger Publishers. Panzar. John. 1979. W. New York: Garland Publishing. Phillips, Almarin, 1971. Tecnnelogy eng Market Structure: A Study of the Aircrafr Ingestry, Lexington, Mass: Heath Lexington Books. Schmalensee, Richard., 1977. "Comparitive Static Properties of Regulated Airline Oligopolies," ell Journa of Eeononics 8(2):565-576. Schmidt, Peter, and Robin C. Sickles, 1984. "Production Frontiers and Panel Data," Qenrnel e: Pnsiness end Eeonemic Stetistice 2(4):367-374. 169 Sharkey, William W., 1982. T e heo of Natural Mono ol Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sickles, Robin C., 1985. "A Nonlinear Multivariate Error Components Analysis of Technology and Specific Factor Productivity Growth with an Application to the U.S. Airlines," Journal of Eeonomeprics 27:61-78. Sickles, Robin C., David Good , and Richard L. Johnson, 1986. "Allocative Distortions and the Regulatory Transition of the U.S. Airline Industry," Journal of Econometrics 33(1/2):143-163. Simat, Helliesen and Eichner, Inc., 1980. Deneetic Air Fare Changes Under the Airline Deregulation Act of 1978, New York: Simat, Helliesen and Eichner, Inc. Sinha, Dipenda, 1986. "The Theory of Contestable Markets and U. S. Airline Deregulation: A Survey, " T_h_e WW 22(4)=405- 420- Smith, Myron J., Jr., 1986. Airline iblio ra h : The e Col e e Gu to ur s o Commer ial Avierien, Velnne l; The Qnitee Steres, West Cornwall, Conn.: Locust Hill Press. Spiller, Pablo T., 1983. "The Differential Impact of Airline Regulation in Individual Firms and Markets: An Empirical Analysis," u a of and Economics 26: 655-689 . Strassman, Diana L., 1986. "Contestable Markets and Dynamic Limit Pricing in the Deregulated Airline Industry: An Empirical Test," Unpublished paper, Rice University. Straszheim, Mahlon R., 1978. "Airline Demand Functions in the North Atlantic and Their Pricing Implications, " W 12(2):179- 195. 170 Teodorovic, Dusan, and Slobodan Gubernic, 1984. "Optimal Dispatching Strategy on an Airline Network After a Schedule Perturbation," EurODean Journal of Qperational Researcn 15(2):178-182. Trapani, John M., and Clinton V. Olson, 1982. "An Analysis of Impact of Open Entry on Price and Quality of Service in the Airline Industry," Peview of Economics and Statistics 64(1):67-76. Toh, Rex S., and Richard G. Higgins, 1985. "The Impact of Hub and Spoke Network Centralization and Route Monopoly on Domestic Airl ine Prof itabil ity , " Transportation Journal 25(4):16-27. "U.S. Airlines and Deregulation," Aviation Week Q Space Technology, November 8, 1982:81-120. United States Civil Aeronautics Board, 1975. Report Of the CAB §pecial Stag; en Regnlarog Reform Washington, D.C.: Civil Aeronautics Board. ---. 1974. The Qomespie Pente Sysren, Anelysis and Policy Recommendations, Washington, D.C.: Civil Aeronautics Board. White, Lawrence J ., 1972. "Quality Variation When Prices Are Regulated," Bell Journal of Economics 3:425-436. Wilkins, Bill, 1984. "Airline Deregulation: Neoclassical Theory as Public Policy," Journal of Eeonomic lssues 18(2): Wolfe, Harry P., and D.A. NewMeyer, 1985. Aviation Industry Begelerien, Carbondale, IL: Southern Illinois University Press. Yance, Joseph V., 1972. "Non-price Competition in Jet Aircraft Capacity," Jeurnel of Industrial Economics 21(3):55-71. "7'1111111'111‘1111'8