,I.‘ ‘Uc Cl. .1 v 05. t. u c . fizu. I . I: 'I c .3 {lzvr‘llllblfvt 1.31:1. .4. Kurd: .‘0 L’fi‘jl' tiéifivf 0:.“ 1 'I - .l‘allzl . 1".“ I if...) «6‘. .n 1 4 u? r I I Ali-Pd: A .3 '1: « Earl. .33? in 304.3” ., .: 9.11} [.1 up, ,rpldp? . a. 71V o; LI .0. . rlplulfv .o otnuu‘cho fiat! J . pr IKE-1.1 . 5 . «aha: ffiufiru u... . p v I‘D ’- {an a , a. u.» .r: 34.4». r. lfluue: . (It. . .1: b‘510.1-f‘ .1.O..vo.a.il.l I}! "On. Ill-til . . )‘Ct’i”! Up)???” 51% éfinfiuu : 4|! I. I; l A D I ,Ihatl‘tl‘lifl§¢.‘r’ .‘ . o In... «lulu. I b: ‘ ‘ \ l I A v 3%.. “(£835 illlllmlIlllllllllliHlllflllllllllHMINIIHIIIIIIUIIHW 3 1293 00792 I _\ ' LIBRARY Michigan state University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled The Economics of Consumer Response to Health-Risk Information in Food presented by Sedef Emine Akgungor has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. Mgmem Agricultural Economics (:3 <’”E?:> “fig“ :29;/ M~M1¢'(-§ Major professor Date‘3’7/6Vzmbé/L it; /9 9 (1 MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0‘ 12771 PLACE IN RETURN BOX to removeth checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 4 W MSU to An Affirmative ActiorVEquel Opportunity Institution omens-9.1 THE ECONOMICS OF CONSUMER RESPONSE TO HEALTH-RISK INFORMATION IN FOOD By Sedef Emine Akgungor A Dissertation Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1992 ABSTRACT THE ECONOMICS OF CONSUMER RESPONSE TO HEALTH RISK INFORMATION IN FOOD By Sedef Emine Akgiingér This research extends previous research on the demand effects of health concerns regarding Alar residues in apples. Following this previous research, an econometric model for retail fresh apple demand is developed for the New York City (NYC) retail apple market. However, a longer time series is used to estimate apple demand and two improvements are made to the demand model. One of these improvements incorporates the possibility that the national retail price and thus the NYC retail price may be affected by health-risk information at the national level. Therefore, the NYC demand equation is tested for simultaneity bias. The second improvement is in the modeling of seasonality in per capita apple purchases and retail apple price variables. The results indicate that simultaneity bias is not an issue in estimating the retail apple demand in the NYC market. Therefore, the NYC apple demand is estimated by a single equation. A multiplicative seasonal ARMA model appears to represent seasonality in per capita apple purchases and retail apple price variables. As found in the previous research, apple demand was found to shift downward immediately following the initial announcement of health risk in July 1984. Demand recovered fully when Alar was withdrawn from the market in June 1989. This finding suggests that sales losses could have been avoided had the Government recalled Alar in 1984 since the majority of the drop in sales is due to the initial and sustained shift in demand. Following previous research, consumer’s willingness to pay to avoid Alar residues in apples was calculated using the estimated demand model. Consumer’s marginal Sedef Emine Akgflngdr willingness to pay for risk reduction was calculated by dividing the annual willingness to pay to avoid Alar by estimates of consumers’ perceived amount of risk avoided per year. As found in previous research, the estimates of consumer willingness to pay to avoid health risks suggest that consumers reacted to the health risks associated with Alar as they have to other health risks. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS There are many peOple who helped me to make my years at Michigan State University most valuable. First, I thank Eileen van Ravenswaay, my major professor and dissertation supervisor. Having the opportunity to work with her over the years was intellectually rewarding and fulfilling. I owe her much gratitude for her guidance and careful reading of the drafts of this dissertation. I also thank Dr. John Hoehn who contributed much to the development of this research starting from the very early stages of my dissertation work. Dr. Richard Baillie provided valuable contributions to the development of the econometric model. I thank him for his insightful suggestions and experience. I also want to thank Dr. Jeff Wooldridge for his prompt and useful suggestions for the various specific econometric problems along the way. Many thanks to the Department computer staff, especially to Margaret Beaver who patiently answered my questions and problems on word processing. I owe much thanks to Ege University, School of Agriculture, Department of Agricultural Economics in Izmir, Turkey, for financially supporting me for my graduate studies abroad. The funding of this project was provided in part by the US. Environmental Protection Agency Cooperative Agreement (#CR-815424-01-2), the Michigan Agricultural Experiment Station Project #3800, and the Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University. Their financial support is greatly appreciated. I would like to thank to my peer graduate students in the Department of Agricultural Economics who helped me to feel much like at home here in the United States. My special thanks go to Ellen Fitzpatrick and Lih-Chyun Sun whose friendship and support I deeply value. I thank Nuran Erol for her close and enduring friendship over the years. The last word of thanks go to my family. I thank my parents, Saer and Uner Birkan and my brother, Emre Birkan for their patience and encouragement. Lastly I thank my husband, Kadir, for his endless support through this long and seemingly endless journey. TABLE OF CONTENTS Page List of Tables ........................................................ x List of Figures ....................................................... xi CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION ................................................... 1 1.1 Background ............................................. 3 1.2 Problem Statement and Scope of Research ..................... 4 1.3 Importance of Research .................................... 5 1.4 Existing Empirical Evidence on the Impact of the Alar Incident on Apple Purchases .......................................... 5 1.5 Research Objectives ....................................... 8 1.6 Research Procedures ..................................... 10 1.7 Description of the Data ................................... 12 1.8 Plan for the Presentation of the Research ..................... 12 CHAPTER II CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK ....................................... 14 2.1 A Model of Consumption Choice ............................ 14 2.1.1 Definition of the Terms: Health Problem, Health Risk and Health-Risk Perception .............................. 14 2.1.2 The Model of Consumption Choice .................... 21 vi 2.2 Specifying the Information Variables ......................... 2.3 Hypotheses on Modelling the Information Effect ................ 2.4 Methods for Valuing the Welfare Effects of the Health-Risk Information ............................................ CHAPTER III THE ECONOMETRIC MODEL ....................................... 3.1 An Econometric Model for Apples ........................... 3.2 The Reduced-Form Equations and the Demand Equation ......... 3.2.1 The Reduced-Form Equation for Per Capita Apple Purchases in NYC Region .................................... 3.2.2 The Reduced-Form Equation for Deflated Retail Apple Price in the NYC Region ................................. 3.2.3 Interpretation of the Estimates for the Coefficients on the Information Variables in the Reduced-Form Equations ..... 3.2.4 Hypotheses on the Information Effect on Reduced-Form Equations and Demand Equation ...................... 3.3 Methods for Estimating the Reduced-Form Equations and the Demand Equation ....................................... 3.3.1 Specifying Time»Series Model for the 1n and the ln Variables ........................................ 3.3.2 The Estimation Procedure for the Demand Equation and Methods to Detect Simultaneity Bias ................... CHAPTER IV THE ECONOMETRIC RESULTS ...................................... 4.1 Specifying a Time-Series Model for the Quantity and the Price Variables .............................................. 4.1.1 Methods for Determining a Stochastic Model for the Error Term ........................................... 4.1.2 Identification ..................................... 4.1.3 Estimation and Diagnostic Checking .................... 23 26 29 32 33 38 39 41 42 44 51 52 55 56 59 4.2 Checking for Sirnultaneity Bias in the Demand Equation .......... 61 4.3 The Information Effect on the NYC Region’s Apple Demand for the January 1980-July 1989 Observation Period .................... 64 4.4 The Information Effect on the NYC Region’s Apple Demand for the January 1980-July 1991 Observation Period .................... 72 4.5 The Information Effect on Quantity and Price in the Reduced-Form Equations .............................................. 76 4.6 Estimating the Change in Revenue to the NYC Region Fresh Apple Retailers .............................................. 84 4.7 Estimating the Change in Consumer Surplus Associated With the Risk Information ........................................ 86 CHAPTER V CONCLUSIONS, POLICY ISSUES, AND FURTHER RESEARCH ........... 90 5.1 Summary of Research Problem and Methods ................... 93 5.2 Summary of the Research Results ........................... 93 5.2.1 The Importance of Considering Seasonality when Estimating the Regression Equation ............................. 93 5.2.2 Sirnultaneity Bias in the Demand Equation .............. 95 5.2.3 Information Effect ................................. 96 5.2.4 Own-Price Elasticities ............................... 97 5.2.5 Change in Total Apple Sales Associated with the Information on Alar .......................................... 97 5.2.6 Change in Consumer Surplus Associated with Information on Alar ............................................ 97 5.3 Policy Issues ............................................ 98 5.4 Needs for Future Research ................................ 100 APPENDIX A: DESCRIPTION OF DATA .............................. 102 APPENDIX B: THE DATA .......................................... 108 APPENDIX C: WEEKLY DATA ON EARNINGS ......................... 118 viii APPENDIX D: DERIVATION OF THE REDUCED-FORM EQUATIONS FOR 45 AND p,’ ................................................. 131 APPENDIX B: THE ASYMPTOTIC COVARIANCE MATRIX FOR THE TWO- STAGE LEAST SQUARES ESTIMATOR WITH SEASONAL ARIMA ERRORS .................................................... 137 APPENDIX F: EHECTED VALUE OF THE CHANGE IN APPLE SALES ASSOCIATED WITH HEALTH RISK INFORMATION ............... 146 APPENDIX G: EXPECTED VALUE OF THE CHANGE IN THE CONSUNIER SURPLUS ASSOCIATED WITH HEALTH-RISK INFORMATION ...... 150 BIBLIOGRAPHY ................................................... 153 LIST OF TABLES Page Table 4.1. Estimate of Seasonal ARMA models for Per Capita Apple Consumption and Retail Price of Apples in the NYC Region (January 1980-July 1989) ............................................... 60 Table 4.2. Estimate of the Demand Equation With Seasonal ARMA Errors With and Without an Instrument for the Price Variable (January 1980-July 1991) ....................................................... 63 Table 4.3. Estimate of the Demand Equation With Seasonal ARMA Errors (January 1980-July 1989) ........................................ 66 Table 4.4. Estimate of the Demand Equation With Seasonal ARMA Errors (January 1980-July 1989) ........................................ 68 Table 4.5. Estimate of the Demand Equation With AR(1) Errors (January 1980- July 1989) ................................................... 70 Table 4.6. Estimate of the Demand Equation With Seasonal ARMA Errors Under Different Specifications for the Information Variable (January 1980-July 1991) ............................................... 73 Table 4.7. Estimate of the Reduced-Form Equation for Per Capita Apple Purchases With Seasonal ARMA Errors ............................ 78 Table 4.8. Estimate of the Reduced-Form Equation for Retail Apple Price With Seasonal ARMA Errors ......................................... 80 Table 4.9. Estimates of Total Apple Sales in the New York Region With and Without the Effect of Alar for the July 1984-June 1989 Period (1983 Dollars) ..................................................... 87 Table 4.10. The Expected Value of the Annual Change in Consumer Surplus Under Alternative Elasticity Estimates (1983 Dollars) .................. 89 Table 4.11. The Implicit Willingness to Pay for an Annual Reduction of One in One Million (1 x 10‘) Risk of Cancer Death (1983 Dollars) ............. 91 Table 4.12. Definitions of the Variables Used in the Econometric Model ......... 92 LIST OF FIGURES Page Figure 3.1 Hypothesis I .............................................. 46 Figure 3.2 Hypothesis II .............................................. 47 Figure 3.3 Hypothesis 111, Case 1 ....................................... 48 Figure 3.4 Hypothesis 1]], Case 2 ....................................... 49 Figure 3.5 Hypothesis 111, Case 3 ....................................... 50 Figure 3.6 Hypothesis IV ............................................. 51 Figure 4.1. Estimates of the Apple Sales in the New York Region With and Without the Risk Information (Model 4) ................................... 85 Figure 4.2. Estimates of the Apple Sales in the New York Region With and Without the Risk Information (Model 5) ................................... 86 Figure A.1. Retail Fresh Apple Prices (1983 Dollars) and Per Capita Fresh Apple Purchases in the NYC Region (Pounds) ............................ 107 Figure F .1. Change in Apple Sales Asociated With Health-Risk Information ...... 146 Figure G.1. Change in Consumer Surplus Associated with Health-Risk Information .................................................. 150 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION Consumer concerns about the safety of the food supply, especially about the safety of pesticide residues in food, have been high during the past decade.1 These concerns appear to be due to new information that consumers have received about the potential health risks of pesticide residues in food. These risks are conveyed by new information about the toxicity and presence of pesticide resides in food. An example of this is the Alar incident. Alar is a growth regulator primarily used on apples. In 1984, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) announced that it would reevaluate its risk assessment for Alar because of the evidence that Alar and its derivative UDMH cause cancer in laboratory animals. The toxicity of Alar was debated for five years by the experts, the food industry, the government and the producer of Alar, Uniroyal. The news media widely reported this dispute and thus caused a large impact on consumer purchases of apples.2 Alar was taken off the market by Uniroyal in June of 1984, and subsequently banned for use in apple production by the EPA. 1Julie A. Caswell, ed., W (New York. Elseiver Science Publishing Co.,1991). 2Eileen van Ravenswaay and John P. Hoehn, ”The Impact of Health Risk Information on Food Demand: A Case Study of Alar and Apples," in W SALE. ed. Julie A. Caswell (New York. Elseiver Science Publishing Co.,1991),p.p 155- 174; A. Desmond O’Rourke, "Anatomy of a Disaster,” Agribusiness 6 (1990), pp. 417- 424; Boyd M. Buxton, "Economic Impact of Consumer Health Concerns About Alar on APP1$"EMLWMWK "IFS-250 Economic Research Service, United States Department of Agriculture (August 1989), pp. 85-88. 1 2 van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) found that the demand for apples in the New York-Newark (NYC) metropolitan area1 declined after the disclosure of health-risk information associated with lifetime consumption of apples treated with Alar. They examined the effect of the Alar incident on apple purchases until July 1989, one month after Uniroyal removed the chemical from the market. They were therefore unable to detect whether the Alar controversy caused any long-term effects to the NYC apple market. After the withdrawal of Alar from the market several alternative scenarios regarding apple demand in the NYC market could have followed. One is that the demand for apples may have recovered fully when consumers received information that Alar was no longer on the market. This would imply that consumers responded swiftly to the information available to them. Another alternative is that it may have taken several periods of demonstrated product safety until consumers believed the apples were safe to eat. The last alternative is that the demand for apples never shifted back to the pre-product warning levels such that there remains a permanent effect in the NYC region apple market. This would have occurred if consumers who have shifted away from apple consumption to apple substitutes during the Alar scare did not return to consuming apples because of their lack of confidence in the apple market or simply because they become accustomed to consuming apple substitutes. It is not possible to determine which scenario applies to the NYC apple market unless we include the months after the chemical was removed from the market. To find out the long-term effects of the Alar incident, this research extends the previous research by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) by increasing the observation period to the months after the withdrawal of Alar from the market. This research also examines some particular 1During the presentation of the research, the expressions ”NYC region" and "NYC market" will be used to represent the region that covers the New York-Newark metropolitan area. 3 problems in econometric modeling, including seasonality and sirnultaneity bias, which are discussed in more detail below. 1.1 ac ou The Alar controversy began in July of 1984 when the EPA announced that Alar, the trade name for the chemical Daminozide, and its derivative UDMH were potential carcinogens. The EPA’s decision not to ban Alar from the market at that time stimulated a debate between Government officials, consumer groups, and industry about the health risks of Alar. The debate continued through June 1989, when the chemical was removed from the market by Uniroyal, the manufacturer of Alar. The public debate was most controversial between February 1989 through June 1989; the news coverage of the Alar controversy was also its heaviest then. In February 1989, EPA announced that it would ban Alar within the next 18 months, when the tests were complete. During the following days, consumer groups criticized EPA for not banning Alar promptly. Later that month, a CBS Mm program focused on the findings of the Natural Resources Defense Council (NRDC) on the cancer risks to children from Alar and other pesticides in food.1 During this month, the NRDC announced its risk estimate from Alar, and the EPA released a revised risk estimate.2 Uniroyal stopped most of its overseas sales of Alar in October 1989. The company claims that it continues to believe in the safety of Alar, but the domestic market for Alar had deteriorated so much that it was uneconomical to continue lBradford H. Sewell and Robin M. Whyatt, "Intolerable Risk: Pesticides in Our Children’s Food" (Washington, DC: Natural Resources Defense Council, 1989). 2For the chronology of the Alar incident from July 1984 through June 1989 see Eileen van Ravenswaay and John Hoehn, 1991. This chronology is based on the review of articles on Alar in the New York Times during that period. 4 production for the overseas market alone.1 In November 1990, almost two years after the N RDC’s report, a group of apple growers filed a law suit against CBS for airing the program that reported the NRDC’s findings in March 1989 and against NRDC for declaring misleading statements to the public. The industry’s estimate of the sales losses to the growers after February 1989 was $100 million.2 As seen from the chronology, there are three major events that mark the Alar incident. The first is the EPA’s initial announcement in July 1984 that Alar was a potential carcinogen. The second is the events surrounding the publicity of the NRDC’s and EPA’s findings and the W program in February 1989. The third is the voluntary ban on Alar use in June 1989 followed by the Government ban. To understand the long-term effects of the Alar controversy on apple purchases, it is necessary to look at apple demand patterns after 1989, the date when the chemical was removed from the market. 12 W11 This research analyzed how health-risk information about food afi'ects food purchases over time by systematically identifying measures of the presence or absence of risk information in the market and incorporating these variables into an econometric demand model. Using the econometric model, estimates of how consumers value improvements in the safety of the food supply were developed. More specifically, this research investigated the long-term effect of the Alar incident on fresh apple purchases in the NYC retail apple market, and examined what consumers were willing to pay to avoid health risks associated with the consumption of Alar treated apples. 1Allan R. Gold, ”Company Ends Use of Apple Chemical,” We; 18 October 1989, p. A18. 2"After Scare, Suit by Apple Farmers," W 29 November 1990, p. A22. 5 One of the major reasons that we chose the NYC metropolitan area is to be able to follow up on the findings of van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) by extending their data set through July 1991 to examine the demand patterns after Alar was removed from the market. The NYC market was originally chosen by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) due to the availability of the most comprehensive price data. 1.3 Wasatch The findings from this study have significant implications for the government and the food industry. An understanding of how consumers have reacted to the Alar incident and how the demand patterns have changed after risk was eliminated from the market provides guidance to policy makers in responding to consumer fears in similar health- scare events. The food industry also benefits from such knowledge in developing strategies to prepare for similar incidents. An estimate of the economic consequences of the Alar event provides an important piece of evidence for the apple industry in quantifying the revenue losses associated with the controversy on Alar. Another finding from this study is an estimate of the consumer’s willingness to pay to avoid Alar residues in apples. From that willingness to pay estimate, it is possible to assess consumer’s valuation of risk-reduction benefits. This piece of information is valuable for policy makers in evaluating policy alternatives concerning food safety improvements. 1.4 -A, 1‘ 110_!.¥€-'."l';'11‘H.221. rs; .19"!°lé'fi‘ Buxton (1989) examined the impact of the Alar incident on Washington State red delicious FOB prices. He compared the actual weekly FOB prices during the 1988-1989 marketing season with the expected prices that usually occur over a typical season. The 6 typical season price pattern was calculated based on the FOB prices for Washington State red delicious apples at the Wenatchee shipping point. The seasonal index was estimated by removing trend, cyclical and irregular price changes from the actual price series for the period of January 1983-March 1989. The author found that the FOB prices of red delicious apples fell after February 1989, the time that the news coverage on Alar was the most intense. The findings suggest that over the period starting in late February through the second week in September, the total revenue loss for the growers of red delicious apples in Washington was $140 million in 1989 dollars. The author also reports that the retail prices did not reflect the full decline in the FOB prices which made it harder to market apples remaining in storage. O’Rourke (1991) examined the impact of the Alar incident on Washington State FOB shipping point apple prices. Washington State is considered the major supplier of apples to the U.S. market. Therefore, the impact of the Alar incident on the Washington State apple industry may be a good proxy for its impact on the US wholesale apple market. The author used existing price forecasting models developed by the Washington Growers Clearing Association for Red Delicious, Golden Delicious and Granny Smith apples, and projected what the FOB shipping point apple prices would have been had the Alar incident not occurred. The method he used in calculating the revenue change to the apple growers is to subtract the observed values of the actual 1988-1989 average FOB shipping point prices from the apple prices that were projected from the price forecasting models. His findings suggest that the apple industry lost $130 million in the 19884989 marketing season (in 1989 dollars). Red delicious was the variety most affected by the Alar scare. van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) examined the effect of the Alar scare in the NYC retail fresh apple market. The authors used a single-equation demand model to estimate demand for apples in the NYC region using a time series model. Monthly data from January 1980 through July 1989 were used. They found that the effect of the Alar 7 incident dated back to the time when EPA first announced in July 1984 that Alar was a potential carcinogen. The study reported that over July 1984-July 1989 period, 70% of the estimated total sales losses to NYC region’s retailers was attributable to the initial and sustained demand shift in July of 1984. The sales loss estimate was calculated by subtracting estimated actual apple sales from a projection of what sales would have been had the Alar incident never occurred. The sales loss estimate for the period of June 1984 through July 1989 was $194.8 million (in 1983 dollars). The authors estimated consumer’s willingness to pay to avoid Alar treated apples and use this estimate to calculate willingness to pay to avoid cancer risks. They found that the willingness to pay for reduced cancer risks were consistent with the existing estimates of willingness to pay for reduced risk in the literature. The findings of the above studies provide empirical evidence that the Alar incident caused a reduction in apple purchases. It should be noted, however, that the three studies differ from each other in several important aspects. For example, van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) showed that the change in apple sales associated with the Alar incident started in 1984 and much of the sales losses are attributable to that event while Buxton (1989) and O’Rourke (1991) examined the Alar incident only for the 1988- 1989 marketing season. Another notable difference is associated with the methods used in the three studies in calculating the revenue losses due to the Alar scare. Buxton (1989) and O’Rourke (1991) subtract the pm apple prices from the W Mild apple prices and multiply the difference with the actual quantity sold. van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) subtract the M apple sales from the estimated W apple sales. The reason why van Ravenswaay and Hoehn use this method is to minimize estimation errors.l Still another difference between these three 1See, Mark E. Smith, Eileen 0. van Ravenswaay, and Stanley R. Thompson, "Sales Loss Determination in Food Contamination Incidents: An Application to Milk Bans in Hawaii.” We 70 (August 1988). pp. 513-520- 8 studies is that Buxton (1989) and O’Rourke (1991) examine the impact of the Alar scare on the wholesale apple market while the study by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn covers the retail apple market. For these reasons, it is not possible to compare the quantitative findings from these three studies. All three studies, however, indicate that there is a downward demand shift at the apple market. O’Rourke’s findings indicate that the national wholesale prices dropped in 1988-1989 marketing season as a result of a downward demand shift at the wholesale market, given that the supply of apples at the wholesale market is perfectly elastic. Buxton also concludes that the Washington State red delicious apple FOB prices fell as a result of a downward shift in wholesale apple demand. van Ravenswaay and Hoehn model the retail apple market at the NYC region and found that the demand at the retail level also shifts down. This research examined the long term effects of the Alar scare by extending the observation period of the study by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). This was the major objective of the research. Several other objectives were also sought as listed below. 1.5 Emmhghisctixcs 1. The long-term effects of the Alar incident are estimated by extending the observation period used in the van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) study to the period after the withdrawal of Alar from the market. 2. The possibility that the Alar incident may have affected the retail price of fresh apples at the retail market is examined. If the retail price of apples at the national market is affected, then the retail price of apples in the NYC region should also be affected under the assumption of perfectly elastic supply to the regional markets. If information about risk at the national level affected the national demand and thus 9 national apple price, representing the NYC apple demand with a single equation would cause the equation estimates to be inconsistent and biased. The estimated demand model should therefore be tested for sirnultaneity bias. This objective involves specifying an econometric model for apples that involves the national retail market and the regional retail markets for apples. This enables us to form testable hypotheses about the effect of health-risk information on apple purchases at the regional level when the event actually covers the whole nation. 3. Alternative measures of the health-risk information variable are explored. 4. Improved methods to account for seasonality in apple purchases are developed. Seasonality means there is a high degree of correlation between the values observed during the same season across the years. 5. The findings of this model, which explicitly accounts for the seasonal error structure, are compared to the findings obtained with a first order autoregressive error structure reported in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). The comparison will be made for the January 1980-July 1989 period to maintain consistency with the observation period covered in the van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) study. This study will then extend the observation period through July 1991 and compare the models with the seasonal error structure for the two observation periods (i.e. January 1980-July 1989 period and January 1980-July 1991 period). This comparison allows us to observe how extending the observation period changes the equation estimates. 6. The change in revenues associated with the Alar event to the NYC apple retailers are estimated. 7. The impact of the Alar event on consumer welfare is estimated. This objective involves calculating the change in consumer surplus associated with the health- risk information and deriving the consumer’s willingness to pay to avoid Alar residues in apples. 10 8. From the estimate of the consumer’s willingness to pay to avoid Alar residues in apples, the consumer’s willingness to pay for health-risk reduction is derived. As the objectives stated above show, this research differs from the study by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) in at least three aspects. One is the extension of the observation period to include the period after Alar was removed from the market. The second is the correction for seasonality in the demand model. This allows us to detect the impact of the exogenous variables on quantity demanded in isolation of the variations in apple sales associated with seasonality. The third difference is that this research models the effect on regional apple prices of potential price adjustments in national markets caused by the Alar controversy. 1.6 W The research methods consist of the procedures listed below. 1. An econometric model of national retail demand and supply for fresh apples, retail apple demand for all the regions in the nation except the NYC region, and retail apple demand for the NYC region is developed. 2. The reduced-form equations for per capita apple consumption and the retail price of apples in the NYC region is derived. 3. The reduced-form equations and the demand equation for apples in the NYC region is used to derive testable hypotheses about the impact of health-risk information on per capita apple purchases and the retail price of apples in that region. These hypotheses test whether risk information affects purchases at the regional level through a regional demand shift, or through a change in the national price induced by information at the national level, or through both effects. 11 4. Alternative measures of the presence or absence of the reported risk over time are developed. Testable hypotheses to specify the information effect on apple demand are developed. 5. A seasonal time-series model of per capita apple consumption and apple prices variables is specified. 6. Simultaneity bias in the demand equation is examined. This procedure involves derivation of the asymptotic covariance matrix for the demand equation where the price variable is replaced by the fitted values for the price variable and the error structure of the demand equation is seasonal.1 7. The demand equation and the reduced-form equations are estimated using a seasonal error structure. 8. The significance of the coefficients of the information variables in the demand equation for the January 1980 through July 1989 observation period are compared with W These are the first order autoregressive error structure and the seasonal error structure. 9. The significance of the coefficients for the information variables are compared with the seasonal error structure for the WM. These are the periods of January 1980 through July 1989, and January 1980 through July 1991. 10. Hypotheses on different specifications of the information effect in the demand equation are tested for the extended observation period, that is the January 1980 through July 1991 period. 1 1. Changes in apple sales associated with changes in health-risk information are estimated in the NYC region. 1The reason that the estimate of the covariance matrix for the demand equation with instrument for the price variable is separately calculated is because we are not able to do the two-stage least squares estimation and get the coefficient estimates as well as the asymptotic covariance matrix with the "BOXJENK" command in the Regression Analysis Time Series (RATS) econometric package (version 3.1) for personal computers which is used in this study to compute multiplicative seasonal ARIMA model. 12 12. Changes in consumer welfare associated with changes in health-risk information are estimated by computing the change in consumer surplus. 13. The consumer’s implicit willingness to pay to avoid a one in one million risk of cancer death is computed using the estimate of the change in consumer surplus. 1.7 Description of the Data Since this research is an extension of the study by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn, the data for the period between January 1980 through July 1989 is largely identical with the data used in that study.1 There are two major differences, however. One difference is that the monthly population estimates that are used in this research covers a smaller area. The other difference is the inclusion of an income variable and a variable that measures the national holdings of fresh apples. Appendix A presents the description of the data used in this study. Appendix B reports the extended data set. 1.8 W Chapter II develops a conceptual framework to analyze consumer response to information on health-risk from food. This chapter defines the information variables and states the hypotheses related to the information effect on the quantity of food demanded. Methods to quantify the welfare effects associated with the changes in health-risk information is presented later in the chapter. Chapter III presents the econometric model for apples. This chapter discusses the estimation procedures for the regression equations. Chapter IV presents the econometric findings of the research and 1F or a detailed description of the data used in Eileen van Ravenswaay and John Hoehn, 1991, see William Preston Guyton, "Consumer Response to Risk Information: A Case Study of the Impact of Alar Scare on New York City Fresh Apple Demand" (MS. Thesis, Michigan State University, 1990). 13 discussion of the results. Chapter V presents the research conclusions, policy issues and research needs. CHAPTER II CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK This chapter develops a conceptual framework for the analysis of consumer response to information on health risk from food. Section One presents a model of consumption choice that establishes a relationship between health-risk information and the demand for risky food. Section Two explains how the information variable in the demand equation is defined. Section Three states the hypotheses concerning the effect of health-risk information on food purchases. Section Four describes the methods used to measure the welfare changes associated with the changes in information on health risk. 2.1 Wills: This section first defines the terms used in the conceptual framework. The section then presents the consumer’s optimization problem and derives the demand functions for risky and non-risky foods. There are two concepts closely related to a consumer’s W [is]; from any source in his/her lifetime. The first one is the Wills that the consumer expects to experience during his/her lifetime. The second one is the 14 15 probability that a health problem will occur during the consumer’s lifetime. This second concept is the W of the consumer. There is a range of health problems that the consumer can face. Each is characterized by the type of health problem, the severity of the health problem, the duration of the symptoms, and the timing of their occurrence in the lifetime of the consumer.1 Some examples of the type of health problem that the consumer might expect to face during a lifetime are cancer, allergies, ulcer, heart diseases, etc. The severity refers to the seriousness of the health problem. Curable cancer, for example, is less severe than incurable cancer. The duration is the amount of time that the health problem persists. The timing in a lifetime relates to the age the consumer expects he/ she will be when the health problem is realized. For the purpose of this study, we assume that there is only one health problem in the lifetime of the consumer. The type of health problem, its severity, duration, and timing in the lifetime of the consumer are well defined. The lifetime health risk of the consumer is the probability that the health problem will occur during the consumer’s lifetime. This is the actual health risk that is unknown to the consumer before he/ she receives health-risk information. We assume lifetime health risk is a random variable since we assume there is a range of heath-risk levels for the consumer at a given point in his/her lifetime. The probabilities associated with the likelihood of the occurrences of a range of lifetime health-risk levels are unknown until the consumer receives exogenous information on the riskiness of practicing a specific activity or consuming a particular food. The acquisition of the information can be considered a random experiment and the probabilities associated with the likelihood of the occurrences of a range of lifetime health-risk levels cannot be predicted with certainty prior to the experiment. These lNicholas Reseller. WWWLM W (New York: University Press of America, 1983). 16 probabilities constitute a probability distribution. This probability distribution is the consumer’s lifetime health-risk perception function. The concept of the lifetime health-risk perception function suggests that each level of health risk is associated with the consumer’s perception of the likelihood of its occurrence during a lifetime. Since the perceived lifetime health risk is defined as a distribution function, it can be characterized by measures of center, such as mean, median or mode. In this study, for convenience, the consumer’s health risk perception function will be characterized by the health-risk level that has the highest perceived probability of occurrence for the consumer (i.e., mode of the lifetime health-risk perception function). Therefore, the consumer’s perceived lifetime health risk is the health risk level that the consumer considers most likely to happen. In summary, the consumer’s perceived lifetime health risk can be defined with the help of two concepts. One is the set of health problems that may result from all causes. Each health problem is characterized by the type, severity, duration, and timing in the consumer’s lifetime. Note that the set is assumed to have only one element. The characteristics of the health problem are well defined. The second concept is the probability of the occurrence of the health problem in a lifetime. This is the lifetime health risk. With the aid of exogenous information, the consumer forms a probability distribution where each probability is the likelihood of the occurrence of the lifetime health risk. This is the consumer’s health risk perception function. The conSumer’s perceived lifetime health risk is the health risk level that the consumer believes to have the highest probability of occurrence in the health risk perception function. There are two types of health risks that the consumer faces in his/ her lifetime. One is the baseline health risk associated with all the activities in the consumer’s lifetime except the lifetime consumption of Alar-treated apples. These include dietary habits, smoking, alcohol consumption and nonconsumption activities such as driving a car, being 17 exposed to radioactive substances, etc. The other one is the additional health risk associated only with the lifetime consumption of Alar-treated apples. We assume that the lifetime health risk is additive. That is, it consists of the baseline health risk pig the additional health risk from consuming Alar-treated apples. Perceived lifetime health risk is also assumed to be additive. The consumer has a perceived baseline health risk and a perceived additional health risk that add up to the perceived lifetime health risk. Assume that the consumer lives for three periods. The first period is all the time that has elapsed until the present time; it is denoted by the subscript 0. Since the consumption decisions from this period have already been made, the health consequences due to consumption in the past are taken as given. The second period is the present period; it is denoted by the subscript t. The third period is the future; it is denoted by the subscript f. The perception of the chances that the consumer will experience the health problem in the future period is xf= dove-t b,v,+ poqo-t- Pr‘lv where v0 and vt are the quantities of the activities other than the consumption of Alar-treated apples in the past and present periods, respectively. qo and q, are apple consumption in the past and present periods, respectively. 60 and b, are the consumer’s past and present perception of the marginal probability of the occurrence of the future health problem associated with an addjmmal unit of all other activities except the consumption of Alar-treated apples, respectively. 60 and 6, are the consumer’s perceived baseline marginal health risk. p0 and p, are the consumer’s past and present perception of the marginal probability of the occurrence of the health problem associated with consumption of an m unit of Alar-treated apples, respectively. po and p, constitute the consumer’s perceived additional marginal health risk. We also assume that v consists of two types of activities, v1 and v2, both at time o and time t. Here, v1 includes consumer’s preventive actions (i.e., investment in health care, exercise) and v2 includes all other activities. The 18 consumer reduces his/her chances that he/she will experience the health problem in the future, rrf, by making changes in the consumption of v and q at times 0 and t. For simplicity, we assume that the consumer finds it less costly to reduce marginal risk from consuming Alar treated apples by reducing his/her consumption of q rather than increasing his/ her consumption of v2. 60 and p0 are functions of the consumer’s knowledge about the marginal risk associated with the consumer’s choice of v and q in the past period. Since this period is already past, the risk consequences (bovo-I- poqo) associated with the past choice of these goods and activities are taken as given. 5, and pt are functions of the consumer’s knowledge about the marginal risk associated with the consumer’s choice of v and q in the present period. We assume that the consumer receives information in the present period on the WW associated with an mm of Alar-treated apples. The consumer receives information through signals from a given information source. The signals differ by their informational contents. The informational content of a signal indicates the presence or absence of risk in apples. The presence or absence of risk can be determined by the information on residue and toxicity. The toxicity of a substance and how much residue there is in the food supply are essential aspects of the food safety question.1 Toxicity information is information about how toxic or hazardous a particular substance is. It is the information about the dose-response relationship for a given exposure level. The dose-response information defines the health risk concerning the consumer’s exposure to the risky food. For example the lifetime health risk given the lifetime exposure to the risky food may be 1 in 10,000 cancer deaths. Residue information is information on the amount of 1Eileen van Ravenswaay, "Consumer Perceptions of Health Risks In Food, in W (Oakbrookt Farm Foundation, 1990). 19 substance in the food supply. A consumer’s exposure to the substance over a lifetime is a function of the per-unit amount of residue as well as the total consumption of the risky food. The lifetime health risk is a function of both the toxicity and the lifetime exposure. Note that the reported risk in the present period is the MM associated with an mm of Alar treated apples. With the aid of this information, the consumer forms pt, his/ her perception of the WM that is the marginal probability of the occurrence of the health problem associated with the consumption of an W of Alar treated apple at time t. The reason why the consumer can make this inference is because the reported lifetime health risk is assumed to be proportional to the marginal health risk as explained in the paragraph below. Let the reported risk be E, where i is the lifetime health risk associated with lifetime consumption of Alar treated apples. The lifetime health risk is assumed to increase linearly with the consumption of the risky food. This is a result of the assumption of the linear dose-response model.l Therefore, the lifetime health risk can be annualized if we divide it by the consumer’s life expectancy (i.e., 70 years): 5' = (RHO), where 5 is the annual health risk associated with an average annual consumption of Alar treated apples. This implies that E = F at 71', where E is the average annual consumption of Alar treated apples and 7 is the marginal health risk associated with the consumption of one unit of Alar treated apple. Therefore, F = 5'15 . In summary, the reported risk (i.e., E) is the lifetime health risk associated with the lifetime consumption of Alar treated apples. By the assumption of the linear dose- response model, the annual health risk associated with an average annual consumption of apples (i.e., S") is proportional to i. Since the marginal health risk associated with the lEileen van Ravenswaay and John Hoehn, 1991. 20 consumption of one unit of Alar treated apple (i.e., F) is proportional to E, we can say that the reported risk R is proportional to F as well. The perception of the marginal probability of the occurrence of the health problem associated with consumption of an additional unit of Alar-treated apple in the present period (p,) is a function of the currently available information on the presence or absence of risk. Note that the po, 60 and 6, are taken as given. The currently available information can be measured in several ways. The following two ways are used. One is by the timing of government announcements about new lifetime risks. The other is by counting repetitions of these announcements by the media per time period. The repetitions of the government’s announcements about risk are important because the consumer’s assessment of the magnitude of the health problem may be subject to learning. That is, the magnitude of a consumer’s perception of risk may increase as he/ she hears more often about the presence of risk. Therefore, pt is characterized as a function of two variables. One variable measures the presence or absence of the risk by the timing of its initial announcement (d,). The other variable measures the presence or absence of the risk by the number of times the same message is repeated at a given point of time (g,). (2.1) o, = 9.81.3) To summarize, the consumer is assumed to live for three periods: the past, the present and the, future. The consumer’s perceived risk of experiencing the health problem in the future period is the sum of the perceived health risk associated with all activities except the consumption of Alar-treated apples and the perceived health risk associated with the consumption of Alar-treated apples in the past and in the present periods. In the present period, the consumer receives new information on the presence or the absence of health risk associated with the consumption of apples treated with 21 Alar. With the aid of this information, the consumer updates the perception of the probability of experiencing the health problem in the future period. The next section discusses the consumer’s optimization problem and derives the demand function for apples. 2.1.2 The Model of Consumption Choice The model of consumption choice in this study is based on the expected utility model. This framework is useful in the food-safety context since consumption decisions are made in the presence of uncertainty.1 Assume that the consumer’s preferences are separable. That is, preferences can be partitioned into groups such that the preferences within each group can be described independently of the quantities in other groups.2 Following this assumption, food will be defined as a separate group. Assume that the representative consumer consumes q (apples) and y (all other foods) during a lifetime. Among all food items, assume that only apples contain residues of a particular toxic substance (Alar). The lifetime expected utility of the consumer is, (2.2) EU a U,(q,y) +191: Ufi(q,y) +(1 -t)*vfi(qu) where, 1!, = 9oVo*5r"t*Poqc*Pflr and p‘ = p'(d',g’). Here, U,(q,,y,) is the utility of the consumer in the current period and Uh(qf,y,) is the utility associated with poor health lean E. Choi and Helen H. Jensen, "Modelling the Effect of Risk on Food Demand,” in Economig of Fggd Safety, ed. Julie A.Caswell (New York: Elseiver Science Publishing Company, 1991), pp. 28-44; Young Sook Eom, ”Pesticide Residues and Averting Behavior" (Raleigh: North Carolina State University, Division of Economics and Business, February, 1991), photocopy. 2Angus Deaton and John Muellbauer, ' e (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1980), pp. 122- 125. 22 and Ufl,(qf,yf) is the utility associated with good health in the future. qt and y, are consumption of apples and all other foods in the present period, respectively. q: and y, are consumption of apples and all other foods in the future period, respectively. 1:, is the consumer’s perceived probability of the occurrence of the future health problem, after consuming qo and v0 in the past period and qt and vt in the present period. Note that we assume that the past and present consumption is irrelevant to the current period’s utility, i.e., the health effects are always delayed to the future period. We also assume that there are no marginal health risks associated with the future consumption. The optimization problem of the consumer is to maximize (2.2) subject to the lifetime budget constraint. The lifetime budget constraint is, (2.3) m = 154 + 19,? where m is the consumer’s lifetime disposable real income, pq is the deflated retail price of apples, p" is the deflated retail price of all other foods, q is the quantity of apple consumption in a lifetime and y is the quantity of all other foods in a lifetime. Note that m, pq and py are assumed to be constant over a lifetime. Therefore the per-period budget constraint (i.e., the budget constraint at time t) is proportional to the lifetime budget constraint. The lagrangian expression for the utility maximization is, (2.4) L . ”‘(q’y)+n"u"(q’y) +0 4') * Up(4ry)”'("'t’Pflr'Pfl) where, 2. is the Lagrange multiplier. Here, m,, pqt and p,, be the consumer’s disposable real income, the deflated retail price of apples and the deflated retail price of all other foods at time t, respectively .The first order conditions for this problem are shown in equation (2.5). If the consumer maximizes utility, equation (2.6) will express his/her demand for q and y in the present period. U 9-1: - —1+p,vfi-p,ufi 1P, - o 8 8 an (2.5) 21; . _‘._),p" e o 8 3 6L qr = qro’qnpyt’mr’pr) y. = rips-PM») (2.6) Since pt is defined as a function of d, and g,, the demand functions for q and y in the current period are as shown in equation (2.7). q. = qfls-Pymrdrs) y. = marshes) (2.7) To summarize, the demand for q (apples) is a function of its own price, the price of its substitutes, income and health-risk information available at time t. The health-risk information is measured by two variables. One represents government announcements about risk and the other represents the repetitions of the announcements. The following section discusses alternative ways in which the information variable can be measured and incorporated in the demand function. 2-2 Spraifidnsihslnfcunaucnlar'ahlcs Following van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991), the information variables (d, and g,) in this study are measured by news media reports about Alar’s health risks. The announcements of new risks are identified by dummy variables. The variables S1, and 82, represent the two occasions when different estimates of health risk were announced. S1, represents the July 1984 to June 1989 period. It begins with EPA’s initial announcement 24 in July 1984 that Alar was a potential carcinogen which EPA subsequently estimated as posing a lifetime cancer risk to food consumers of 1.0* 10".1 The period ends in June 1989 with the removal of Alar from the market. Consequently, S1t takes the value of 1 between July 1984 through June 1989 and zero in all other months. 32, marks the beginning of the period during which the N RDC announced a greater lifetime risk estimate of 2.4"‘10‘4 and the EPA simultaneously released a revised risk estimate of 3.5*10'5. This is the period after February 1989 that lasted until Alar was removed from the market. Consequently, 82, has the value of 1 between February 1989 through June 1989 and zero elsewhere. The underlying hypothesis for this type of measurement of information is that the initial announcements of the health risk matters for the consumer. SI, is hypothesized to cause a sustained downward shift in demand associated with the initial announcement by the EPA as found by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). However, the effect of this announcement is assumed to disappear upon the withdrawal of Alar from the market. Following van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991), 82, is hypothesized to cause an additional downward shift in demand associated with the simultaneously reported revised risk estimates of the EPA and the NRDC. This shift was also sustained through June 1989. The announcements of the revised risk estimates suggest the existence of a new event that increased the consumer’s perceived risk level, thus causing apple purchases to decline even further. There is a third variable that is measured with the nominal scale. This variable (83,) measures the effect of the withdrawal of Alar from the market. If the sales returned to the pro-announcement levels, S1, and 82, should be sufficient to represent the variations in sales during the Alar controversy given the way that these variables are defined. S3t should then not bring any additional explanatory power to the model and 1F or the reported lifetime cancer risk estimates associated with consumption of Alar from all food sources, see, Eileen van Ravenswaay and John Hoehn (1991). 25 should not be statistically different than zero, while S1, and SZt should be negative and significant. It is possible that the intensity of news reporting on risk announcements is important in explaining the variations in apple purchases. This may be true if the risk perceptions involve learning such that the magnitude of the consumer’s perceived risk increases with subsequent repetitions of announcements. Therefore, a measure of the intensity of the reporting over time should be considered. An information variable can be constructed such that the risk information is identified by the number of media reports per time period (NYTt). Using the intensity variable, we can test the hypothesis that the intensity of the coverage of the health risk is important for the consumers in making their consumption decisions. Lagged values of the NYTt variable can also be incorporated in the model to test whether the intensity of coverage affects future consumption or only current consumption. The intensity of information can also be measured by the cumulative amount of reporting at a given point in time. The information variable that is measured by the cumulative number of articles over time can be incorporated in the demand model to test the hypothesis that consumers update their risk perceptions with the receipt of new information. This variable is not stationary, however, since it involves a time trend. In econometric models that use time-series data, the dependent variable and the independent variables should both be stationary. To eliminate the nonstationarity problem, one can difference the variable. For example in a time-series model that involves a highly seasonal dependent variable, such as apple purchases, both the dependent variable and the independent variables may be seasonally differenced to eliminate nonstationarity in the variables. After seasonally differencing, however, the cumulative variable will no longer measure the cumulative number of articles, but will measure the total number of articles in a given year. This makes it difficult to interpret the coefficient estimate. For these reasons, the information variable that measures the 26 presence or absence of risk with the cumulative number of articles will not be incorporated into the econometric model. In summary, the information variables in this study are measured using both a nominal scale and an interval scale. The nominal scale uses the beginning of the two events during which the different risk estimates were announced to account for the one time demand shift associated with each event. Another information variable using the nominal scale is the variable that measures the presence or absence of the suspected chemical in the market. The interval scale measures the intensity of the reported risk by the amount of media reporting on risk each time period. 2-3 W The hypotheses outlined in this section will be tested for the models that use monthly observations from January 1980-July 1989 as well as for the models estimated using the extended observation period through July 1991. This will allow us to compare the models with seasonal error structure for two different observation periods. We will then be able to understand if the extension of the observation period affects the model estimates. We will also be able to explore the long-term effects of the Alar controversy. We can also compare the models under two different error structures for the observation period of January 1980 to July 1989. This allows us to see how a seasonal error structure changes the model estimates when compared to a first-order autoregressive error structure. The first hypothesis is that information about Alar’s risk does not affect fresh apple purchases. If we reject the first hypothesis, then the following four hypotheses about the impact of risk information on apple purchases will follow. Hypothesis two is that consumers do not forget the information that health risk is present until they receive an announcement that it is no longer present. In other words, 27 consumers do not forget information that is still relevant to their well being. We use 81,, the dummy variable that measures the presence or absence of the health risk to test this hypothesis. Hypothesis three is that the intensity of the reporting of risk intensifies consumer risk perceptions and causes apple sales to drop. If this hypothesis is true, then the coefficient on the NYTt variable and / or the lagged values of the NYTt variable should be negative and significant. However, the period during which there was intense media coverage involves the month in which the EPA announced a revised risk estimate and the NRDC released its risk estimate (February 1989). Therefore, a different hypothesis could be that announcements on the presence of risk is important to consumers in determining their risk perceptions and thus their apple purchases. The presence or absence of these levels of health risk is measured by 82,. It is not possible to test the two hypotheses separately since either or both explanations may be true. Since 82, is likely to be correlated with the current and lagged values of the intensity variable, including these variables as separate regressors would cause a problem of multicollinearity. We can estimate two separate models, i.e., one model with the current and lagged values of the NYTt and another model with 82,. However, we would not be able to know which specification represents hypothesis three. In other words, we cannot separate out the effect of the variable that measures the intensity of the media coverage from the variable that measures the presence or absence of the risk estimates made in February 1989. There is not sufficient information to differentiate what the real cause of the drop in apple sales between February 1989 through June 1989 was. It could have been the announcement of the risk estimate made by the NRDC and a subsequent one made by the EPA in February 1989, or it could have been the intense media coverage stirred by the public controversy over what the correct risk assessment was which also was during that period. We would only be able to distinguish the effect of the NYTt variable on per 28 capita apple purchases had the two events (i.e., the announcement of revised risk estimates and the intense media coverage) occurred in separate time periods. Hypothesis four is that consumers do not forget the initial risk information and they continuously revise and update their risk perceptions as they receive new information about risk. This hypothesis is likely to be true if there is a downward shift in apple demand associated with the initial announcement of risk coupled with an additional downward shift in demand when additional risks are reported. Similar to hypothesis three, note that we are not able to distinguish what the real cause of this additional drop in sales was since the period of the intense media coverage on the presence of risk involves February 1989, the month in which the revised risk estimates were released. W are used to test this hypothesis. In one specification, the information variables would be S1‘ and the current and / or the lagged values of the NYTt variable. This represents the added effect of the intense media coverage. In another specification, the information variables would be S1, and 82,. This represents the added effect of higher risks reported by the NRDC and lower risks reported by the EPA. We do not reject hypothesis four if the coefficient on the S1, variable and on the current and / or the lagged values of the NYTt variable is significant. Similarly, we do not reject hypothesis four if the SI, and 53, are negative and significant. Note that S1t represents the initial shift in demand associated with the initial information on health risk. The current and lagged values of the NYTt variable and the 5,, variable represent the additional shift in demand. However, we do not know the real reason for the additional drop in sales. One reason may be that the consumer may react to the intense media coverage such that his/ her perception of health risk may increase. The increased risk perception causes an additional downward shift in demand. Another reason may be that the announcement of the revised risk estimate of the EPA and the estimate made by the NRDC may intensify consumer’s risk perceptions and this may cause an additional downward shift in demand. Similar to hypothesis three, both 29 specifications must be true and we cannot differentiate between the models. We would be able to differentiate the reason why this additional downward shift in apple demand occurs had the two events (different risk estimates and the intense media coverage) happened in non-overlapping time periods. The fifth hypothesis is that sales return to the pre-announcement levels once the reported risk is declared to be eliminated from the market. This implies that consumers regain confidence in the safety of the supply of apples once they receive a signal that indicates the risk is no longer present. This hypothesis is likely to be correct if consumers who switched to the apple substitutes during the Alar scare went back to their old purchasing habits after the heath risk is eliminated. 83,, which measures the presence or absence of the chemical in the market, is used to test this hypothesis. If the fifth hypothesis is true, this variable should not provide any additional explanatory power to the equation estimates when the variables that represent the presence or absence of the risk are negative and significant, given the way S1, and 82, are defined. 2.4 u‘ Ion... .0 V1. 1’ I‘ WC: 8 it'll 0 I‘ trusty-i I 0 II; '1 After an appropriate specification of the information variable in the demand function, the welfare effects of the Alar controversy can be estimated. By observing the shifts in demand function associated with the changes in health-risk information, it is possible to derive the marginal willingness to pay to avoid Alar residues in apples and to use this estimate to derive an estimate of the willingness to pay for a unit change in risk. This approach has been used in other studies that look at the welfare effects of the health-risk information1 1Pauline M. Ippolitto and Richard A. Ippolitto, "Measuring the Value of Life Saving From Consumer Reaction to New Information," WM 25 (1984), pp. 53-81; Eileen van Ravenswaay and John P. Hoehn, 1991. 30 The Hicksian compensating and equivalent measures are considered to be the correct theoretical measures of welfare. The compensating variation is the amount of income, paid or received under the prospective policy change, that would leave an individual at the initial level of utility. The equivalent variation is the amount of income, paid or received, that would leave an individual at the post-change level of utility when faced with the initial policy situation.1 Willig demonstrates that the consumer surplus is a close approximation to the Hicksian measures of welfare when the budget share of a commodity is Small? The welfare measure used in this study is the change in consumer’s surplus due to a shift in an individual’s apple demand associated with health-risk information. The share of apple expenditures in an individual’s budget can be considered small. Following Willig, the Marshallian demand should approximate the Hicksian welfare measures. Therefore, observing the change in consumer surplus with and without the risk information will give the individual’s willingness to pay to avoid Alar residues in apples. This willingness to pay estimate reflects the individual’s total welfare change associated with the Alar incident. The underlying assumption in the econometric model in this study is that the supply of apples to the NYC region is perfectly elastic at the national price plus a fixed transportation cost. Therefore, the quantity demanded is hypothesized to vary with changes in health-risk information at m. This implies that change in health- risk information causes a shift in the individual demand curve 1John P. Hoehn and Douglas Kreiger, V ' Staff Paper no. 88-30 (East Lansing: Michigan Sate University, Department of Agricultural Economics, 1988). 2Robert D. Willig, “Consumer Surplus Without Apology," Worms; Rm 66(4) (September 1976), pp. 589-597. . 31 and thus reduces the quantity of apples the individual consumes. The change in individual welfare comes from consuming less apples to avoid health risks associated with the consumption of Alar-treated apples. The individual willingness to pay for avoiding Alar residues in apples at a given level of price at time t is, W = 1;ng .MJJP - Ltqupxnfip where q(.) is the apple demand function, pqt is the retail price of apples, py, is the retail (2.8) price of apple substitutes, tilt is disposable income, to is the absence of the reported risk and f1 is the presence of the reported risk at time t.1 p' denotes the given level of price at time. The annual total willingness to pay can be obtained by summing the total willingness to pay at each time t over a year. Dividing the estimate of the individual’s annual total willingness to pay to avoid health risks from consuming Alar-treated apples by the individual’s perception of the annual health risks due to Alar residues in apples gives the individual’s annual marginal willingness to pay to avoid health risks associated with Alar incident.2 However, the consumer’s perceptions of health risks associated with the consumption of apples with Alar residues are not known. Following van Ravenswaay and Hoehn, the next best approach is to assume that the consumer’s perception of health risks are sirnilar to the health risks reported in the media. 1Note that the presence or the absence of the reported risk is measured in various ways as discussed in section 2.2. For convenience, the symbol ft will account for the risk information in general. inleen van Ravenswaay and John P. Hoehn, 1991. CHAPTER III THE ECONOMETRIC MODEL Chapter 111 describes the econometric model used to estimate the retail demand for apples and to examine the impact of health-risk information on apple purchases. Section One presents the econometric model for apples. The econometric model consists of the retail apple demand equation for the NYC region, the retail apple demand equation for all other regions, and the retail apple demand and supply equations for the nation. The model assumes that the national price and the quantity consumed of apples are determined simultaneously by the national apple supply and demand. We also assume that the supply of apples at the regional level is perfectly elastic at the national price plus a fixed transportation cost to the region. Section Two specifies the reduced-form equations for per capita quantity purchased and for the price of apples in the NYC region. The section then explores the relationships between the coefficient estimates for the information variables in the quantity and price reduced-form equations and in the demand equation for the NYC region. The hypotheses on the effect of information on price and quantity in the reduced-form equations and on quantity on the demand equation are stated later in the section. Section Three discusses the methods used to detect seasonality and to construct a stochastic model for the error structure associated with the price and the quantity variables. It then explains the estimation procedure for the demand equation. 32 33 3.1 n etic ode or es In developing an econometric model for apples in a regional market such as the NYC market, the supply and demand relationships at the national market and at the regional markets should be jointly examined using a system of equations. This is justified by the assumption that price and quantity are determined simultaneously in the national market and that the supply of apples to the regional markets is perfectly elastic. We assume that there are two regions in the national retail fresh apple market: the NYC region and the aggregate of all other regions. The national price of apples is determined by national supply and demand. The supply of apples to the NYC region and all other regions is assumed to be perfectly elastic at the national price plus a fixed transportation cost. For convenience, we assume that the transportation cost to the NYC region is greater than zero and the transportation cost to all other regions is equal to zero. This implies that the retail price of apples in the NYC region is greater than the national retail price by a fixed proportion and the retail price of apples in all other regions is equal to the national retail price. The econometric model for apples can be expressed in the following four equations. The retail apple demand equation for the NYC region is: as' - Bin; + Bin: * 9;”: + Biff + 0t (3.1) p}. = (l + m; = up; such that 00, p‘,’ <0 and p; <0. The sign of the numerator determines the sign of the coefficient estimate of the information variable in the reduced-form equation for price. The information coefficients in the numerator of the reduced-form equation for price are p; which corresponds to the supply shift at the national level associated with the health-risk information and 3:45;, which corresponds to the demand shift at the national level. The relative effects of the 1 See equation D.18 in Appendix D. 2 See equation D.12 in Appendix D. 44 demand and the supply shift at the national level determine the impact of information on retail apple price at the national level and thus at the regional level. If the effect of the supply shift at the national level is stronger (weaker) than the effect of the demand shift at the national level, then the price should go up (down). If the two effects are equal, there should be no change in the national price, and thus there should be no change associated with the risk information in the regional price. The following section describes the hypotheses concerning the effect of health- risk information on quantity and price in the reduced-form equations and on quantity in the demand equation. The following four hypotheses represent the efiect of health-risk information on equilibrium level of retail apple price and per capita apple consumption at the NYC retail apple market. By observing the coefficient estimates on the information variables in the reduced-form equations and in the NYC demand equation, we can understand how the equilibrium price and quantity pair at the NYC region was affected by the Alar incident. Note that we are not able to observe the national retail market and all other markets. Therefore, the following hypotheses are based on the estimates of the NYC demand equation (equation (3.1)), the reduced-form equation for per capita apple purchases in the NYC region (equation (3.5)) and the reduced-form equation for deflated retail price in the NYC region (equation (3.8)). The testable hypotheses are on the effect of information on the equilibrium price and quantity pairs at the NYC market from the reduced-form equations. We are also able to estimate the demand curve for apples in the NYC market such that we can observe shifts in the demand curve 45 associated with the Alar incident. Therefore, the hypotheses outlined below are going to be tested by observing the significance of the coefficient estimates on the information variables in the reduced-form equation for quantity (7'), the reduced-form equation for price (a’) and the NYC demand equation (p: ). The algebraic derivation of the estimates of the coefficients for the information variables in the reduced-form equations is presented in Appendix D. As stated in Section 3.2.3 and explicitly derived in Appendix D, the estimates of y, and orr include coefficients for the information variables ’ of the structural equations. The following hypotheses can be interpreted in terms of the expected signs of the coefficients on the information variables in the structural equations as outlined in Section 3.2.3. The first hypothesis is that there is no effect of health-risk information on apple purchases in the NYC region. One explanation of this hypothesis is that the Alar incident had no impact on apple purchases across the nation at all. Another explanation of this hypothesis is represented in Figure 3.1. In Figure 3.1, the Alar incident shifts down the national retail apple demand curve from J: to d; . There is a commensurate supply shift at the national retail market such that the retail supply shifts down from s,“ to s,“ which causes the national retail apple price and thus the price at the regional level remain unchanged, ie, p,“ = pz', p," = p; and p,’ =- p; .1 Since there was no change in demand at the NYC region, the equilibrium per capita apple consumption also remains unchanged, i.e., q,’ =- q; in Figure 3.1. If the retail apple price at the NYC region remains unchanged, then 8' a 0 which implies the effect of the national supply shift on the equilibrium national retail apple price is equal to the effect of the national demand shift as outlined in Section 3.2.3. Since the NYC retail apple demand curve remains unchanged, then 91:0. As seen in equation D.18 in Appendix D, the net effect of 1Note that aside from the possibility of a supply shift at the retail level, there are other explanations of why the national retail apple price and thus the NYC retail apple price was not affected by the Alar incident (see, Section 3.1). 46 information at the NYC level is determined by two components. Therefore, 7' should also be equal to 0. pr“ p°ll pnl ‘2 sn as»; e»: at; = 6; \é ° / \Q :3’ t 0 in oi ' q; q oi oi q of q": q NYC Region Other Regions Nation Figure 3.1 Hypothesis I If the coefficient on the information variable in the reduced-form equation for price (a’) is statistically different than zero, then hypotheses two and three follow. Hypothesis two is that the change in apple sales in the NYC region is due may to a change in the national price induced by health-risk information at the national level. As represented in Figure 3.2, this hypothesis implies that apple demand at the national retail market shifts down from d,“ to d; which causes the national retail apple price to drop from p,” to p; . Subsequently, the equilibrium price at the NYC region drops from p,’ to p; and the equilibrium per capita apple consumption increases from q" to q; as seen in Figure 3.2. According to this hypothesis, there was no downward shift in the demand curve at the NYC region such that d,’ = d; . If the retail apple price at the NYC region drops, then d' < 0 which implies that the effect of the national supply shift on the equilibrium price is less than the effect of the national demand shift as outlined in Section 3.2.3. If the NYC retail apple demand curve remains unchanged, then B: - 0. As seen in equation D.18 in Appendix D, the net effect of information at the NYC level is determined by two components. Therefore, 9' should be less than 0. Note that this 47 hypothesis assumes that there is no supply shift at the national level associated with health-risk information. f O n p ll p I) p II - 2 3,; s" f ’: p: \ v? \ P2 dr P; ‘— o P; x n ’ \a \i 2 t i O n n :qfl q: cl; q R; Qt q2 q1 NYC Region Other Regions Nation Figure 3.2 Hypothesis H Hypothesis three is that the change in apple sales in the NYC region is due to 129111 a change in the national price induced by information and a regional demand shift. This hypothesis is represented under three cases. These cases are represented by Figures 3.3, 3.4 and 3.5. This hypothesis implies that the Alar incident causes a downward demand shift at the NYC region, i.e., the NYC retail apple demand shifts down from d,’ to d; . This hypothesis also implies that the national retail apple demand curve shifts down from d,” to a; such that the price changes from p,” to p; at the national level and thus changes from p,’ to p; at the NYC region as seen in Figures 3.3, 3.4 and 3.5. Since this hypothesis implies that there is a downward demand shift at the NYC region, then 8; <0. The sign on a' and on 7' depends on the following three cases: The first case is that the impact on equilibrium quantity purchased in the NYC region due to a regional demand shift is offset by the change in price at the national level induced by information. Note that in Figure 3.3, the national retail apple demand curve shifts down from d,“ to d; . This means that the national price drops from p,“ to p; and thus the NYC region’s price drops from p,’ to p; as a result of the downward 48 demand shift at the national retail market. The demand curve at the NYC region also shifts down from d,’ to d; such that the equilibrium quantity consumed remains unaffected (q1' = q; ). If the retail apple price at the NYC region drOps, then a' <0 which implies that the effect of the national supply shift on the equilibrium price is less than the effect of the national demand shift as outlined in Section 3.2.3. As seen in equation D.18 in Appendix D, the net effect of information at the NYC level is determined by two components. Therefore the effect of the drop in price on the equilibrium per capita apple consumption at the NYC retail market is even with the effect of the downward demand shift at the NYC retail market such that 7‘ =0. pr II p?) p II 2 n pl \ ,p°\ p:\ i, o 3 = q? = q; q 9°, at q 4'; a? q NYC Region Other Regions Nation Figure 3.3 Hypothesis 111, Case 1 The second case is that the equilibrium per capita apple consumption at the NYC region increased after the Alar incident. The reason is that the impact on qr of the change in price at the national level induced by information is greater than the impact on qr of the demand shift at the regional level. As seen in Figure 3.4, the national retail apple demand shifts down from d" to d: . The downward shift in national retail apple demand shift causes national retail apple price to drop from p: to pz'. Therefore the retail price at the NYC region drops from p,’ to p; . The demand curve at the NYC region also shifts down from d,’ to d; . The equih'brium per capita apple consumption at the NYC region increases from 41' to q; . If the retail apple price at the NYC region 49 drops, then a' <0 which implies that the effect of the national supply shift on the equilibrium price is less than the effect of the national demand shift as outlined in Section 3.2.3. As seen in equation D.18 in Appendix D, the net effect of information at the NYC level is determined by two components. According to this case, the effect of the drop in price on the equilibrium per capita apple consumption at the NYC retail market is greater than the effect of the downward demand shift at the NYC retail market such that 9‘ >0. n Pit Po“ p ll 2 P: \ P: \ P: \ P2 \ o P; h s; 61 \Q’ 40 \Q n P2 «M Q' a; tit q q; q? q NYC Region Other Regions Nation Figure 3.4 Hypothesis 111, Case 2 Note that in both of the above cases, it is assumed that there is no shift in supply at the national level associated with the health-risk information. As seen in Figure 3.5, the third case is that the supply shift at the national level is greater than the national demand shift such that the national apple prices increase from p: to p; due to health-risk information. The equilibrium price at the NYC region therefore increases from p,’ to 1);. The decrease on the equilibrium quantity purchased at the NYC region is associated both with the downward demand shift at the regional level an also with a price increase at the national level. Therefore the equilibrium per capita apple consumption decreases from q,’ to q; . Since the retail apple price at the NYC region increases, then a' > 0 which implies that the effect of the national supply shift on the equilibrium price is greater than the effect of the national demand shift as 50 outlined in Section 3.2.3. As seen in equation D.18 in Appendix D, the net effect of information at the NYC level is determined by two components. Therefore the effect on the equilibrium per capita apple consumption a the NYC region is the sum of the price increase and the downward demand shift at the NYC region such that 7' >0. pl) pll pll 3" fi;\ , n:\ pg. P‘ \ p: \ p1 \,\.; ., : .; ': of <1? :q' :13 of 'q° q; d: 'qn NYC Region Other Regions Nation Figure 3.5 Hypothesis III, Case 3 Hypothesis four is that the change on quantity purchased in the NYC region is due only to a demand shift at the regional level. This hypothesis is represented by Figure 3.6. The national retail apple demand shifts down from d" to d; . There is a commensurate supply shift at the national retail level such that the retail apple supply shifts down from s,” to s,“ such that the national retail apple price remains unaffected after the Alar incident, i.e., p: = p; . If the national price remains unaffected, then the regional prices should also remain unaffected, such that p,“ s p; and p,’ = p; . This hypothesis also implies that there was a downward demand shift at the NYC region such that demand dropped from d,’ to a; such that the equilibrium per capita apple consumption dropped from q,’ to q; as seen in Figure 3.6. Since the retail apple price at the NYC region remains unchanged, then a' = 0 which implies that the effect of the national supply shift on the equilibrium price is equal to the effect of the national demand shift as outlined in Section 3.2.3. As seen in equation D.18 in Appendix D, the net effect of information at the NYC level is determined by thwo components. Since the 51 NYC retail apple demand curve shifts down, then 5; <0. Since there was no effect of information on price, the effect of information on the equilibrium per capita apple consumption at the NYC region should be less than zero (i.e., 9' =0). pr p0 l pn I) g 7 a , ea\ ea‘ \' dr \ ° G d‘ as I \ 45 a? Eq' 4% a? GI° «'2‘ 4: TI“ NYC Region Other Regions Nation Figure 3.6 Hypothesis IV 3.3 U‘ 10L 0 t 11: l’t!‘ i" tk‘n- 0m .19.; II 2-1! I‘ "II-.I! The first step in estimating the reduced-form equations and the demand equation was to determine the error structure associated with their dependent variables: q" and pé. This allows us to account for the time-series component in these variables. It is then possible to explore the effects of the explanatory variables on q,’ and p; in the reduced-form equations and in the demand equation in isolation from the time-series component of the model. Following van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991), the functional form used to estimate the reduced-form equations and the demand equation in this study is log-linear. Therefore, the time series model was specified for the logarithms of q,’ and pg. 52 3.3.1 S ec' ' ' e- e ies Mod 1n ' t e ' Va 'ables When the errors are serially correlated and have a seasonal pattern, they can be modelled by a seasonal integrated autoregressive moving average (Seasonal ARIMA or SARIMA) modelsl. The methods to estimate a time-series model for the error terms associated with the lnq: and lnp: are described in section 4.1.1. After an appropriate specification of the error structures for the dependent variables, the reduced-form equations and the demand equations can be estimated by incorporating the relevant exogenous variables. The econometric model outlined in Section 3.1 suggests that there may be a simultaneity bias in the demand equation due to the impact of the health-risk information at the national level on national, and thus on the regional prices. The following section discusses how the demand equation will be estimated and how a possible Simultaneity bias in the demand equation may be detected. When a regressor is contemporaneously correlated with the disturbance term, estimates are biased and inconsistent. For example, in the NYC region apple demand equation, the apple price variable may be correlated with the disturbance term. One way to deal with this problem is to find an instrument for the regressor. That is, a variable that is correlated with the regressor but not with the disturbance term. Good instrumental variables are hard to find, however. One method is to use the two-stage 1 George. 6 Judge and others, WWW 2d ed. (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1985), pp. 224-271. 53 least squares technique. The two-stage least squares technique is a special case of the instrumental variable method.1 The two-stage least squares method is based on the idea that the exogenous variables in the system of equation are good candidates for being instruments for the variable that is suspected to be correlated with the error term. In this study, this variable is the price variable. The problem is to find out which exogenous variable is the best instrument for the price variable. One suggestion is to regress the price variable on all the exogenous variables in the system and obtain the fitted values for the reduced form. These fitted values can then be used as an instrument for the price variable 9; they can be used in place of the price variables in the demand equation.2 Most econometric software packages can do the instrumental variable estimation and provide the coefficient estimates as well as the estimates of the asymptotic covariance matrix. This procedure can be done both in the linear and the nonlinear least squares context. However, in the presence of a multiplicative error component in the estimation procedure, it is currently not possible to find an econometric package that can do the instrumental variable estimation. An alternative method is to estimate the coefficient estimates for the demand model by applying the two-stage least squares procedure 3 and then calculate the asymptotic covariance matrix for the demand equation. The formula to calculate the asymptotic covariance matrix which is used to calculate the asymptotic covariance matrix for the demand equation with instrument for the price variable is derived in Appendix E. 1Peter Kennedy, p. 134. 2 William H. Greene, pp. 622-624. 3Applying the two stage least squares procedure means that the price variable is first regressed on all the exogenous variables in the system. From this first regression the fitted values of the price variable is obtained. These fitted values are then used as the price variable in a W regression. 54 The presence of sirnultaneity bias in the demand equation may be detected with the specification test developed by Hausman.l Under the null hypothesis of no misspecification, there exists a consistent, asymptotically normal and efficient estimator. The alternative hypothesis is that the estimator will be biased and inconsistent.2 An alternative to the Hausman test for Simultaneity bias in the regression estimate is to perform the regression based specification test.3 This test is based on testing whether the estimated residuals from the equation with no instrumental variables are correlated with a particular linear combination of the exogenous variables in the system.4 1J.A. Hausman, ”Specification Tests in Econometrics,” W 6 (46) (November 1978), pp. 1251-1271. 2Hausman test statistic: (Bu-Bflxcovh-cov‘fkfib- 8d,) , where, 6,, is the vector of coefficient estimates with instrumental variable, 8‘, is the vector of coefficient estimates with no instrumental variable, covh, is the estimate of the covariance matrix with instrumental variable and covniv is the estimate of the covariance matrix with no instrumental variable. Under the null hypothesis, the Hausman test statistic is x’(k) distributed, where k denotes the number of unknown parameters. 3Jeffrey M. Wooldridge, "Score Diognasties for linear Models Estimated by Two Stage Least Squares” (East Lansing: Michigan State University, Department of Economics, October 1992), pp. 20-21, photocopy. ‘The regression based specification test: Let X1, be the set of exogenous variables and be the variable that is suspected to be correlated with the error term (for examp e the price variable in the demand equation in this study). Let 12, be the residuals from the regression with no instruments for the X”. Let X” be the fitted values of the X” when it is regressed on the exogenous variables in the system. The regression based specification test is based on regressing a, on X", X”, and X, and test whether the coefficient estimate on X, is statistically different than zero. If it is zero, this implies that the estimator without the instrumental variable is not biased. CHAPTER IV THE ECONOMETRIC RESULTS This chapter summarizes the econometric findings of the study. Section One starts with describing the methods to determine a stochastic model for the error term. This section then specifies a time-series model for the dependent variables in the demand equation and the reduced-form equations. These variables are per capita apple consumption and apple prices in the NYC region. After the time-series model of the dependent variable is specified, one must determine whether the apple price variable and the error term are correlated in the NYC apple demand equation. This step involves detecting the sirnultaneity bias in the demand equation. It is summarized in Section Two. Section Three and Section Four estimate the demand equation for the different specifications of the information variable and determine the information effect. Section Three outlines the econometric findings for the period of January 1980 through July 1989. This section starts with specification of a time-series model for the dependent variable in the demand equation for the January 1980-July 1989 period. The information variables are then incorporated into the demand equation. The truncated observation period allows us to compare the results with the ones from a nonseasonal specification for the error term that van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) report. The observation period was then extended through July 1991. The results for this observation period are reported in Section Four. Section Five summarizes the findings for the information effect on quantity and price in the reduced-form equations. Section Six reports the estimates of the change in total apple sales associated with the risk information that are computed from the estimated demand models. Section Seven summarizes the estimates 55 56 of the change in consumer surplus associated with the risk information ad derives consumer’s willingness to pay to avoid health risks. 4.1 Spggiflihg g m e-Series Moggl for thg Oughtigz and the Price Vagiables The time-series components for Inc]: and lnpq', were specified using the Box-Jenkins approach. This approach involves three steps: identification, estimation and diagnostic checking. The following section describes the Box-Jenkins approach. 4.1.1 et od te ' ' ast'c t The time-series models offer a framework for predicting the values of a particular variable by observing its past values. This method does not depend on economic knowledge about the process through which the data is generated. The underlying assumption is that the data are generated by a stochastic process. The model that represents this process is defined and estimated by using statistical tools. The Box-Jenkins approach is a method to construct a time-series model for a stochastic process that may have generated the observed data.1 This method consists of three stages: identification, estimation, and diagnostic checking. In the identification stage, a tentative time-series model is specified on the basis of autocorrelations and partial autocorrelations. The autocorrelations are the correlation coefi‘icients between the value of the variable at time t and the value of the same variable lagged a number of periods. The partial autocorrelations show the correlation between the value of the variable at time t and the value of the same variable lagged a number of periods, when the previous lags are already accounted for in the 1For a discussion of the time series models see, for example, George, G. Judge and others. WW PP 224-271 57 model. If a seasonal model is adequate, it is also possible to make a tentative specification for a seasonal time-series model by observing the autocorrelations and the partial autocorrelations. The nonseasonal component of the time series model is illustrated by the following model: (4.1) (1-olL‘-...-¢,Lr)(l-L)‘x,=(1+e,L‘+...+e,Lt):, where, than», = Parameters of the autoregressive (AR) process of order p, 01,...,0' = Parameters of the moving average (MA) process of order q, L = Lag operator, d = Number of differencing, xt = Value of the variable x at time t. In the context of the research, the variable x may be lng,’ or hp}. 5, = Error term at time t. The error term, 5, in equation (4.1) may be correlated with the error terms for the same month across the years. The error term 5’ in April, for example, may be correlated with the error terms in April in the previous years. Seasonality in the data series indicates a high degree of correlation between the values during the same season across years. In the presence of seasonality, multiplicative seasonal models can be used.l Suppose that this relationship can be explained by the following model: (4.2) (1 -Q 11.1 -... ‘0’]. ’Xl -L)D£'s(1 +8‘L ‘ «rm +601, 0k: where, ¢,,...,0, = Parameters of the seasonal autoregressive (AR(Seas)) process of order P, 1(330%? HR BOX and GWilYm M- Jenkins, WW {421111321 (San Francisco: Holden Day, 1976), p. 303. 58 61,...,60 = Parameters of the seasonal moving average (MA(Seas)) process of order Q, L = Lag operator, D = Number of seasonal differencing, 6 Stochastic error term at time t, where 5, ~ N(0,02). 8 Substituting equation (4.2) into equation (4.1) , the following multiplicative model is obtained. (1 -¢,L ‘-... -¢,I. ’)(1 ~01L ‘-...-¢,L ')(1-L)D(l -L)" x,= (4.3) (1+0,L‘+... +6}. ')(1 +91L1 +... +801. °)e, The model represented in equation (4.3) is a multiplicative seasonal integrated autoregressive moving average (ARIMA) model of order (p,d,q)x(P,D,Q)‘, where s is the number of periods that the series show periodic behavior. For example for a monthly data the basic time interval is one month and the period is s= 12. After a tentative ARIMA or multiplicative seasonal ARIMA model is specified and estimated, the model is tested for specification. A common method to test for specification in time-series models is to do a residual analysis. In the residual analysis, the estimated residual autocorrelations are examined. If the residuals of the estimated model are white noise, the residual autocorrelations should be within twice the approximate standard error bounds of the estimated autocorrelations, rah/7‘, where T is the sample size. The overall acceptability of the residual autocorrelations is tested by the portmanteau test statistic (Q-statistic).1 The following section presents the results from each stage of specification for the lag: and the hip; series. 1 Q= 11T+2)2‘T i_r,. Here, the rt are the autocorrelations of the estimated residuals and K ls some prespecified number (for example 1/5 of the total number of observations). The Q statistic is approximately X2-distributed with K-p-q degrees of freedom (see, George E. Judge and others, 0 mm 2d ed., (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1988), p. 705). 59 4.1.2 Identificatign The autocorrelations and the partial autocorrelations of the series are the primary sources in identifying a tirne- series model. The autocorrelation function for both the lnq: and the ln p", variables imply that there is seasonality in the series. The inspection of the autocorrelation functions for these two series suggests nonstationarity in the seasonal component of the series since the autocorrelations for the observations twelve months away do not die out. Both of the series were thus seasonally differenced. After seasonally differencing, we observe the autocorrelation and the partial autocorrelation functions to identify the time-series model. As noted in 4.1.1, time-series models in the presence of seasonality can be modelled as multiplicative ARIMA models. This model involves a seasonal and a nonseasonal component for the error structure. The autocorrelation and the partial autocorrelation functions for the seasonally differenced lnq: and hip; suggest that the seasonal component of the series can be represented by a first-order seasonal moving average model. For the nonseasonal component, the autocorrelation and the partial autocorrelation functions for the seasonally differenced lnq: series recommend a first-order moving average model. The same analysis for the seasonally differenced 111p; variable suggests a first-order autoregression in the series. In summary, after the identification stage the lug: variable is represented by a seasonal multiplicative ARMA model of order (0,0,1)x(0,1,1)12. The 1n 1;; variable is represented by a seasonal multiplicative ARMA model of order (1,0,0)x(0,1,1)12. 4.1.3 Em 3119' n and 123' gngsng' Chfikfll' g After the time-series model is identified, one can estimate the coefficients of the model. The coefficients were estimated using the RATS econometric package (version Table 4.1. Estimate of Seasonal ARMA models for Per Capita Apple Consumption and 60 Retail Price of Apples in the NYC Region (January 1980-July 1989) DEPENDENT Alzln (per capita apple Alzln (retail apple VARIABLE consumption) price) (T = 127) (T: 126)‘ Constant -0.035 . -0.013 (-3201) (-1-044) MA 0.577 . (7.834) AR 0.856 . (17.73) MA(Seas) -0.771 . -0.782 . (-11.618) (-13.461) Q-Stat 23.402 15.043 (lag=24) Ad'. R2 0.590 0.713 (Figures in Parentheses are t-statistics.) ‘ Significant at the as0.01 level ‘Notctmtmc-Bomx-mmmoadmRATScmnomcuicpocnge(mam3.l)rmpcmmmputm drops one observation when estimating a time-series model with an AR(1) error structure. Therefore the number of observations here is 126 instead of 127. A12 : Seasonal difference operator T : Number of observations (The variables are defined in Table 4.12.) 3.1) for personal computers. The "BOXJENK' command in this econometric package uses the nonlinear least squares method to derive the coefficient estimates for the seasonal ARIMA model.1 Table 4.1 reports the estimated time-series models for the lnq: and the hip; variables. To check the overall acceptability of the models, the Q-statisties were examined. The Q-statistic for both models suggest that these specifications correctly represent the 1Note that the nonlinear least squares estimate is not the maximum likelihood since it involves the Jacobian term (Peter Kennedy, p. 344). In deriving the full maximum likelihood estimate it is necessary to take into account the stochastic nature of the vector of starting values. For this reason, ARIMA models that are estimated by the nonlinear least squares method are not the full maximum likelihood estimators but they are approximate maximum likelihood estimators. 61 time-series model for the lnq: and the ln p; variables. The critical value for the fan is equal to 29.62 at the «$0.10 level, where 21 is the degrees of freedom. This number is obtained by subtracting 3 from 24, where 24 is one fifth of the total number of observations and 3 is the number of the estimated seasonal ARMA coefficients (including the constant term). The Q-statistics for both models are lower than the critical value at the 10% significance level. Therefore, we must fail to reject the null hypothesis that there is no serial correlation between the error terms for these two specifications at the 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels. Another check for the specification of the time-series model is to examine the autocorrelations of the residuals. The significance of the residual autocorrelations is compared with twice the approximate standard error of the estimated autocorrelations (HA/7‘), where T is the number of observations. If the estimated residual autocorrelations exceed filfi‘, the model should be reestirnated using a different specification for the error structure. The residual autocorrelations for both of the series suggested that the specifications are acceptable. 4.2Ell'ifi'l'E'lD lE' After the specification of the time-series model of the dependent variable in the demand equation, one must check for Simultaneity bias in the demand equation from the correlation between the apple price variable and the disturbance term in the NYC retail apple demand equation.1 The two methods that are discussed in Section 3 of Chapter III are used to test for simultaneity bias. 1For the source of the possible sirnultaneity bias in the demand equation and methods to detect the Simultaneity bias, see the discussion in Chapter III. 62 To test for sirnultaneity bias, the Hausman test was used to compare the demand equation with the instrument for the price variable with the one without the instrument for the price variable. The first step was to find an instrument for the price variable. An instrument for the price variable was created by regressing the price variable on all the exogenous variables in the system of equations. These exogenous variables are the regional price of bananas, the regional disposable income, the national apple storage holdings and the regional health-risk information.1 The predicted values from this equation were then used as the price variable to estimate the demand equation in a separate regression. Two demand equations were estimated. These are, the demand equation without an instrument for the price variable and the demand equation with an instrument for the price variable. Initially, the other exogenous variables in the demand equations were price of bananas, disposable income and risk information. The price of bananas and the income variables did not provide significant coefficient estimates. Therefore, these variables were excluded from the demand equation. The estimated demand equations are reported in Table 4.2. Note that the covariance matrix for the demand equation with an instrument for the price variable was calculated using the method outlined in Appendix E. The covariance matrix for the demand equation with no instrument for the price variable is the one reported in the regression output of the RATS econometric package (version 3.1). The Hausman test statistic was found to be 0.310. The critical value from the x2 distribution with 5 degrees of freedom at the a $0.10 level is equal to 9.24. Since the Hausman statistic is lower than this critical value, we must fail to reject the null hypothesis that there is no Simultaneity bias in the demand equation when the equation is estimated without an instrument for the price variable at the 1%, 5% and 10% 1The information variables that are used in the demand models when testing for simultaneity bias are the ones that are measured in the nominal scale (Sn, 52,, S3,). 63 Table 4.2. Estimate of the Demand Equation With Seasonal ARMA Errors With and Without an Instrument for the Price Variable (January 1980-July 1991)‘ _ aonetailtestandtheothervariablesarefromatwotailtest. variable are calculated by using the method outlined in Appendix E. (Figures in parentheses are t-statistics.) ’ Significant at the a50.01 level. " Significant at the as 0.05 level. “The dependent variable: A12 lnq,. l"The signficance levels for the coefficients on the lap, and the information variables are from DEMAND” EQUATION DEMAND EQUATION WITH INSTRUMENT WTTH NO MODEL FOR THE PRICE INSTRUMENT FOR VARIABLE‘ THE PRICE VARIABLE‘ (T = 127) (T = 127) ! Constant -0.021 -0.031 (-0.761) (4.419) Ania p, 4.200 0.739 (4.820)" (-2.782)° Assn 0227 0.199 I ('3o547). (“1.678) 0‘ I Ans, -0.396 0314 (-3.883)° (4.107)“ Ans, -0.236 0.105 (4586) (-0.544) MA 0563 0.548 (4541)' (7.103)’ MA(Seas) 0.765 0.780 (40.241)‘ (.11.042)' Adj. Rz 0.628 0.664 SSE 7.027 6.681 Q-Stat 23.165 27.441 (lac-=24) 'The instrument for the price variable was created by regressing [up], on lnpwlnh,,lnm,,S,,,S, and S, to obtain the predicted values for lnpqp ’The estimated standard errors for the demand equation with the instrument for the price .The estimated standard errors for the demand equation with no instrument for the price variable are the ones reported in the output from the RATS econometric package (version 3.1) for personal computers. Au : Seasonal difference operator. T: Number of observations. (The variables are defined in Table 4.12.) significance levels. The regression-based test for the simultaneity bias also supports this finding.1 When the estimated error terms from the demand equation without an instrument for the price variable is regressed on all of the exogenous variables in the demand equation including the price variable M the predicted values for the price variable from regressing price on all the exogenous variables in the system of equations, the t-statistic on the fitted values for the price variable was equal to 1.558. This implies that the estimate of the coefficient for the fitted values for the price variable is not statistically different than zero. We therefore conclude that when the demand equation is estimated without an instrument for the price variable, the residuals are not correlated with the price variable. This implies that there is no problem of simultaneity bias in the estimated demand equation when the observed values for the price variable are included. 4.3 e t' ' n’s d e W2 The time-series component of the lnq: variable for the period of January 1980-July 1989 was specified using the Box-Jenkins approach as discussed in Section 4.1.1. The autocorrelation and the partial autocorrelation functions of the truncated sample also suggest seasonality; seasonal difierencing is thus necessary. After seasonal differencing, the autocorrelations and the partial autocorrelations were reexamined. The time-series component of this variable was specified as a multiplicative seasonal ARMA model of order (0,0,1)x(0,1,1)12. 1For the description of the regression-based test for simultaneity bias, see Section 3.3 .2. 2To maintain consistency in comparing results with the ones reported in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991), the data used for the January 1980-July 1989 observation period is identical to the ones reported in Guyton (1990) 65 After specifying the time-series model of the dependent variable in the demand equation, the next step was to search for the impact of the explanatory variables on the per capita apple purchases by incorporating these variables into the demand equation. The information variables that are initially incorporated are identical to the ones that are reported in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). The same set of information variables from the previous study is used because we want to be able to compare the information effect on per capita apple purchases under two specifications for the error structure in the demand equation for the same observation period. One specification is the AR(1) specification that is reported in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). The other specification is the multiplicative seasonal ARMA specification. The only difference of this model from the one reported in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) is that the variable that measures the presence or the absence of the reported risk by the cumulative number of articles was excluded since this variable is non-stationary. After seasonally differencing the dependent and the independent variables to obtain stationarity in the series, the cumulative variable no longer measures the cumulative effect. Therefore, only the $1,, NYT,, NYTM, NYT,_2 and NYT,_3 were incorporated to the model estimates. The results are reported in Table 4.3. In Table 4.3, the unrestricted model represents the hypothesis that information on risk does not affect apple purchases and it embodies all of the information variables.1 To test the hypothesis that the risk information did not have any effect on apple purchases, the unrestricted model was compared to the model that restricts the coefficients of the information variables to be zero. The likelihood ratio test was 1Note that to maintain consistency with the van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) study, the information variables are S1, and the current and three period lagged NYT3 variable. In this specification, 52, was not included ill the unrestricted model since this variable was not reported among the regression results in the study by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). 66 Table 4.3. Estimate‘ of the Demand Equation” with Seasonal ARMA Errors (January 1980- July 1989)c UNRESTRICTED RESTRICTED MODEL MODEL rr= 100)“ cr= 103) Constant 0.045 0.071 (-1.750)”' (-5.179)‘ A,,ln p, 0.991 0.967 (0337)" (-3250)‘ A,,In p, 0.024 0 .088 (0.069) (0270) Ans, 0.143 (.1059) AM, 0.013 (4304) Alamo: 0.018 (4.705)“ AuNYTn 0.0007 (0.064) ADNYTN 0.010 (0843) 0.658 (8.143)‘ -0.836 . (-11.365)' 0.661 2.134 (Figures in Parentheses are t-statistics.) ‘ Significant at the “0.01 level. “ Significant at the “0.05 level. “‘ Significant at the a$0.10 last. The demand equation was estimated without an instrument for the price variable. ”The dependent variable: Auln q. “The significance levels for the coefficients of the ln pg, 1n p, and the information variables are from a one tail test and the othervariablesare from a twotail test. ‘ Note that T reduces to 100 from 103 when we include a three-period lagged value of the NYT, variable. Au : Seasonal difference operator. T : Number of observations. (The variables are defined in Table 4.12) 67 employed to test this hypothesis.1 The likelihood ratio value was calculated by using the SSRR, the SSRU and the number of observations that are reported in Table 4.3. The likelihood ratio value was 8.17. The critical value in the X2 distribution table at the 5 degrees of freedom is 9.24 at the «$0.10 level. This implies that we fail to reject the null hypothesis at the 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels such that the restricted model is not superior when compared with the unrestricted model. This finding implies that the information variables do not add any additional explanatory power to the demand model at these significance levels. In the above specification of the information variables, when the current and lagged values of the NYTt variable were included in the demand equation as the only information variables, the estimates of the coefficients for the NYTt and the NYT,_1 were significant while the estimates of the coefficients for the NYT,_2 and NYT .3 were not significant. These two variables were therefore excluded from the unrestricted model. The inclusion of the retail price of bananas also fail to provide additional explanatory power to the equation estimates. This variable was thus also eliminated from the equation estimates. The demand model was respecified by using only the apple prices and the remaining information variables as the independent variables. The information variables are the variables that represent the second, third and fourth hypotheses (Sm NYTt, NYT,_1 and $2,) variable. The results are reported in table 4.4. When the restricted model is compared to the unrestricted model, the likelihood ratio value was 7.92. The critical value at the 4 degrees of freedom is 7.78 at the «$0.10 1The likelihood ratio value was obtained by using the following a formula: LR = Te “Mg—U) , where the SSRR is the sum of square residuals obtained from the restricted model, SSRU is the sum of square residuals obtained from the unrestricted model. T is the number of observations. The likelihood ratio value is asymptotically distributed as 12(K) where K represents the number of restrictions. See, Jan Kmenta, Wm 2d ed., (New York: Macmillan Publishing Co., 1986), p. 492. Table 4.4. Estimate‘ of the Demand Equation” With Seasonal ARMA Errors (January 1980-July 1989)c 68 UNREST‘RICTED RESTRICTED MODEL MODEL ('r = 102)‘ (T = 103) Constant 0.043 0.070 (4.779)” (-5.621)' Auln p, 0.965 0.973 (-3301)' (-3.296)' (Figures in Parentheses are t-statistics.) ‘ Significant at the «$0.01 level. ” Significant at the “0.05 level. “‘ Significant at the «$0.10 level. 1114: demand equationwasestimatedwithout aninstrument forthepricevariable. "The dependent variable: Au lnqr 'The significance levels for the coefficients of the lap, and the information variables are from a one tail testanddresignificancelevelsofanothercoefficientsarefromatwotailtest. ‘Note thatT'reduwsto 102 from 103whenweinclude acne-period laggedvalueoftheNYT, variable. Au : Seasonal difference operator. ‘ T : Number of observations. (The variables are defined in Table 4.12.) 69 level, 9.49 at the «$0.05 level and 13.28 at the «$0.01 level. The result suggest that we do not reject the null hypothesis that the information variables are all equal to zero at the 1% and 5% significance levels while we reject it at the 10% significance level. This implies that the unrestricted model in Table 4.4 is superior to the restricted model at the 10% significance level when the error structure is specified with the seasonal error structure. The same hypothesis was tested in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) where the error structure was specified by an AR(1) process. The demand equations from the study by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) were replicated and are reported in Table 4.5.1 When the restricted model is compared with the unrestricted model, the likelihood ratio value was found to be 15.32. The critical value from the X2 distribution at the 6 degrees of freedom is 10.64 at the «$0.10 level, 12.59 at the « $0.05 level and 16.81 at the « $0.01 level. The calculated likelihood ratio value is greater than the 1’ values at the 5% and 10% levels. Therefore we conclude that we must reject the null hypothesis that the information variables are all equal to zero at the 5% and 10% significance levels while we fail to reject at the 1% significance level. This implies that the unrestricted model in Table 4.5 is superior to the restricted model at the 5% and 10% significance levels when the error structure is specified with an AR(1) model. To test which specification of the error structure for the demand equation is correct, the Q-test was applied to the estimated demand equations under the two specifications (the AR(1) specification and the multiplicative seasonal specification). The null hypothesis is that there is no serial correlation between the error terms. When Model 1 in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) is duplicated, the Q-statistic was 36.92. 1Note that the information variables in this model incorporates the information variables of the unrestricted model in Table 4.3 plus the variable that measures the cumulative number of articles on Alar. Also note that the data is identical to the data reported in Guyton (1990), i.e., the population figures covers a larger metropolitan area than the population figures used in this study. 70 Table 4.5. Estimate‘ of the Demand Equation" with AR( 1) Errors (January 1980-July 1989)c UNRESTRICTED l MODEL MODEL (T=111)" Cr=114) Constant -0.631 0.772 I (-1.6l4)' (-1.967)' ‘ ln pg, .2052 -1957 ‘ (6.098)’ (-5-650)' I In p, 0303 0328 ' (0.758) (0.852) ln s,, -0.260 (-1813)‘ CNYT, 0.003 (0.459) NYT, 0.0005 (0.040) NYT... 0.016 (-1250) mm, 0.009 (0.613) NYT,,, 0.017 (.1264) AR 0.587 0.717 (7.135)‘ (10.479)‘ Adj.Ra 0.619 0598 D“! 1.702 1.753 Q-Stat 36.915 36.003 (Ins-=20) SSE 7.352 8.440 (Figuresinl’arenthesesaret-statistics.) ‘ Significant at the «$0.01 level. “ Significant at the a$0.05 level. 'l‘hedemand equationwasestirnatedwithoutanimtrumultforthepricevariable. ’Ihedependentvariable:h1p,. “Thedgnificancelevelsforthecocfficientsofthelnp‘mrp,andtheinforrnationvariablesarefromaone tailtestandthesignificancelevelsofanotherooefficientsarefiomatwotailtest. ‘NotcthatTreduwsto 111fi0m114whcnweindudcathree-periodlaggedvahreoftheNYT,variable. T:Number ofobservations. Clhevariablesaredefinedin'l‘able4JZ.) 7 1 This value is compared with the x209), where 19 is the degrees of freedom. This value is obtained by subtracting 1 from 20. 20 is one fifth of the total observations and 1 is the number of ARMA coefficients in the specification. The critical value from the 12 table at the 19 degrees of freedom is 27.20 at the a $0.10 level, 30.14 at the a $0.05 level and 36.19 at the 0150.01 level. This implies that we reject the null hypothesis that there is no serial correlation at the 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels and the error structure is misspecified with the AR(1) specification. The Q-statistics for the demand models with the seasonal error structure are reported in Table 4.3 and 4.4. These values are compared with the x207), where 17 is obtained by subtracting 3 from 20. 20 is one fifth of the total observations and 3 is the number of the estimated seasonal ARMA coefficients (including the constant term). The critical value from the 12 table at the 17 degrees of freedom is 24.77 at the «$0.10 level, 27.59 at the «$0.05 level and 33.41 as0.01 level. This means that we do not reject the null hypothesis that there is no serial correlation at the 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels. This result suggests that when compared to the AR(1) model, the multiplicative seasonal model is the correct specification for the error structure at the 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels. The results imply that when the seasonal error structure is employed to estimate the demand function over the observation period of January 1980 to July 1989, the information variawa do not add any explanatory power to the equation estimate at the 1% and 5% significance levels while they are all significant at the 10% significance level. The Q-Statistics imply that the seasonal ARMA specification is the correct specification for the demand equation when compared to the AR(1) specification. However, the information variables are significant only at the 10% level with the seasonal ARMA specification while they are significant at the 5% level with the AR(1) specification . Since with the seasonal ARMA specification we are able to reject the null hypothesis that the coefficient estimates of the information variables are all equal to zero only at a 72 higher significance level (10%), it is ambiguous that the Alar incident had any impact on apple demand in the NYC region at all. i In order to find out whether the information about Alar had any impact on apple purchases, the next step is to extend the observation period to see if additional observations would make any difference in the equation estimates. This means that we add 24 more observations to the sample. The following subsection summarizes the findings for the extended observation period. The hypotheses about the effect of risk information on apple purchases were tested by estimating the demand model for the extended time period. The results are reported in Table 4.6. The numbers 1-6 in Table 4.6 indicates the models that embody the hypotheses on modelling the risk information effect presented in 2.3. To test whether the information on Alar had any impact on apple purchases, the unrestricted model (model 1) was compared to the restricted model (model 6) with a likelihood ratio test. The likelihood ratio was 13.98. The critical value at the 5 degrees of freedom is 9.24 at the «$0.10 level, 11.07 at the «$0.05 level and 15.09 at the «$0.01 level. Therefore, the null hypothesis that the restricted model is superior to the unrestricted model was rejected at the 5% and 10% significance levels but not rejected at the 1% significance level. This result implies that there is evidence that all of the information variables are different than zero for the extended observation period since they all are different than zero at the 5% and 10% significance levels. 1The data used to estimate the models for the January 1980-July 1991 observation period are the ones described in Appendix A and reported in Appendix B and C. 73 gamma 8a 3.: Sea 898 82" 8mm 500 82. 28.8 «8.8 33 8% 83 «mm 55 83 :85 «as 986 88.0 R? .523 .3123 .523 .AfinoE .823 .3583 A869 83. 83 83 88. 33 83 <2 has has .996 has bag .38: 82 82 82 88 $2 82 <2 198.3 98.3 198.3 BS. 08°. no.0. :trznq 52¢ 38.3 88.3 5.9 .88.? ~85- E916 32¢ 28.3 88. 23 .84 192.3 93.3 :2. «86. £3 88.3 LEW: $33 68.3 :83 RS. .38. 83. =06 #83 .3283 x820 bani bani .383 . 89o. 88. 83 36.9 «8.? En- tn 5:4 .663 83.3 .933 .Gzi .933 :33 82.. H8? «28. 83. 3.9 5.9 2228 92:8 Sanbm 32...? 5798 57% .62.? doc: .22: b: 783 5:50 finger nous—~83 on“ .8.“ 8038583 “conga .5qu 955 52% Ransom 5m? ocean—Gm vSEoQ 05 .8 .Baflmum 6... mid. 74 3... as“... 3 Bacon an 8525, 25 .maocatumpo .8 838:2 H... .8222? 3:208? Enogom ”:4 673.5, .E 05 we on?» Ecume— votoméao a ova—05 03 non? ha." Sea 8« 2 3032 H :2: Sol 6 .82 :2 oi n . 89c 98 3333, couscous “05° 05 v3 $8 :2 one a Bob 8a 33%? gauges 2: 38 an 5 05 we «gnome—boon. 05 “8 £96. 8588ch of. 6 .65 24 “053.5, Eovcoeuu 2E. n diets, 81a 2: .8.“ 80:5me 5 :55? 33:53 33 82280 “858% BE. . .93 Sewn 2: a 58%me : .352 Sewn 2: a 28%me . “66333.6... 2a 385."on 3 35mm: 95.88 64. 035. 75 Since we fail to reject the first hypothesis that there is no impact of risk information on'purchases and since we do not know what the appropriate specification for the information effect is, the hypotheses that are outlined in Section 2.3 for the alternative specifications of the information effect were tested. The second hypothesis that the consumers do not forget the risk information available to them is embodied in model 2. The estimate for the coefficient on the information variable in this model suggest that we fail to reject the hypothesis meaning that the information about risk is not forgotten until the announcement is made that the source of risk is eliminated from the market. The reason that this hypothesis is not rejected is that the estimate of the coefficient on the Sn variable is significant which implies that there is a one time and a sustained demand shift associated with the initial announcement on the presence of the risk. The third hypothesis is that the intensity of the reporting on the presence or absence of risk intensifies consumer’s risk perception and thus causes a downward shift in individual apple demand. Model 3 incorporates the information variables that represent this hypothesis. Following the discussion in Section 2.3, note that we cannot test this hypothesis with model 3 since the period during which there was intense media coverage on the presence of risk involves February 1989, the month when the revised risk estimates were released. We cannot distinguish the effect of the intensity of the media coverage that is measured by the current and the lagged values of the NYT, variable from the effect of the variable that measures the presence or absence of the revised risk estimates (Sh) since these variables are highly correlated. The correlation coefficient between $2, and NYT. is 0.76 and NYTM is 0.77. Models 4 and 5 incorporate the variables that represent the fourth hypothesis. The coefficients on S1‘ in both models 4 and 5 are significant indicating that there is a one time and a sustained shift in demand with the initial health-risk information in July 1984. The lagged value of the NYTt variable is negative and significant in model 4. The 76 52: variable is negative and significant in model 5. The significance of the coefficients of NYTt,1 and 82, suggests that the consumers continuously revise their risk perceptions when they receive additional information on health-risk. The fifth question is whether there is a long-run effect of the Alar controversy. Model 5 incorporates the S3, variable that measures the presence or the absence of Alar in the market. If the hypothesis that the sales return to the pre-announcement levels is correct, then the coefficient on the 83' should be insignificant while the coefficient estimates on 81, and 52: will be negative and significant. The results suggest that this hypothesis is true. 4.5 atio ua ' d i ' educ - mum After the information effect in the demand equation is specified, the next step is to examine the information effect in the reduced-form equations for quantity and price. As noted in Sections 3.2 and 3.3, by looking at the coefficient estimates of the information variables in the reduced-form equations for quantity and price, we can understand the effect of the health-risk information on the equilibrium price and quantity levels at the NYC region. This section reports the findings on the information effect from the reduced-form equations for quantity and price. As the Hausman test and the regression-based specification test suggest in Section 2 of this Chapter, the simultaneity bias is rejected in the estimated demand equation. This implies that the price variable in the demand equation is not correlated with the error term in this equation. Therefore, if there is a change in per capita apple purchases in the NYC region because of the health-risk information, it is associated only with the demand shift in that region and not with the change in national price due to the 77 information at the national level. The results from the estimated reduced-form equations are also consistent with this finding. Table 4.7 and Table 4.8 report the results from the estimated reduced-form equation for quantity and price, respectively. The numbers 1-6 in Tables 4.7 and 4.8 indicate the models that embody the hypotheses presented in Section 2.3. The results are used to discuss the hypotheses on the information coefficients in the reduced-form equations and in the demand equation. The hypotheses on the effect of information on the reduced-form equations and on the demand equation are outlined in Section 3.2.4. The first hypothesis is that there is no effect of health-er information on apple purchases in the NYC region. If this hypothesis is true, then the coefficient estimates of the information variables in the reduced-form equations for price and quantity and the demand equation should all be zero, i.e, ‘9' =0, a' =0 and 0; =0. This hypothesis is rejected since in the sections above, we already concluded that risk information is a significant variable in the demand equation. The second hypothesis is that the change in apple sales is associated only with the change in apple prices in the national market induced by risk information. If this hypothesis is true, then the coefficient estimate for the information variable in the reduced-form equation for price should be greater than zero, i.e., a' > 0 and the coefficient estimate for the information variable in the demand equation should be insignifieant, i.e., B: = 0. 'lhis hypothesis is rejected since the estimated coefficients for all of the information variables in the reduced-form equation for price are statistically equal to zero since the likelihood ratio value that compares model 1 (unrestricted model) to model 6 (restricted model) in Table 4.8 is 2.98. The critical value at the 5 degrees of freedom is 9.24 at the «$0.10 level, 11.07 at the «$0.05 level and 15.09 at the a $0.01 level. Since 2.98 is smaller than these critical values, we conclude that the information variables are statistically not different than zero. Furthermore, we already concluded in Section 4.4 that the coefficient estimates for the information variables in 78 5.3 ”9.3 :3” 888 :92 was .560 E: as.» was :2 on: «as «3 an. no.9 was «8.0 as 3.0 3.3 .8843 2333 .3863 .8253 .83.:3 .9303 SS. 83. 5.9 9.3 85.9 $3. 939.32 .988 .523 .383 .233 .825 .883 32 Ed :3 «So 82 22 <2 LE3 .983 L8...3 mod. «.86. «8.9 .52 "a 88.3 .1933 A53 28. «8.9 29? EE :4 883 83.3 $3. «8.9 .m :4 I333 98.3 9.8. 23. am .6 183.3 -383 .333 99.3 3.8. $8. and. 83. ._m =4 $8.5 98.8 523 £98.: £98 93.: a8 38 Q3 53 :8 23 a .6 lead $8.8 :83 163.3 38.8 5.3 32. a8 83 RS. 32 and. .e 5.5. $83 :83 63.3 88.3 L53 83.3 Kg 33. :3 £3 02.9 5.9 .a 2:4 .83.”.3 88.3 -683 -983 .323 A803 n86. 89o. ~80. ~86. mad. «8.? 2228 57.5... 57.6“ 62.9. SE: 92...? .82.? doc: avg—ohm (32¢. Enemaom £5 moms—UH: 039‘ 235 “on .5.“ .32an Eoméoosvum 2: no 8.35am .5. as: 79 3... 2...... a. 382. 2.. 83...... 25 «8253.... .o .352 a. .2223 8535—. flag . =< 653.9 .E 05 mo 02.5 comma— eotoaéuo a 3:3 oi «2.3 5 82a and 8 «82.0.. h. .25 202 o .8. =8 25 a 69a 2.. 23.0508 22.... .1... 22.2 8:85.22 2.. .2... .8. .3 26 a as. a. 8......» 8:38.... 2.. .o 2288.8 2.. 2.. 226. 8.555.. 2.... . é... 2.. "2.2.: .5293. 2.... . .25. Same 2.. .. 3.23.2 :. .26. 8...“: 2.. .. saga .. .25. Same 2.. .. .555... . ..a.....§.. a. 8858.... a. 82.2.... £9.89 .56 03:... 80 canto RS. 222 ~82 .82 «8.2 :2. .320 2...... 8.... 82.... 52.... .5... .83 2mm :8 8:. 8:. 8.... 8:. 2.... 2.8... .8833 .8823 .882.-. .533 .8853 .8223 E... 22.. E... E? 3.9 8...... 838...: .8223 88.2. .8223 .892. .85.: .882. $2. .2... 2...... 8.... 2.2. 82. a... 82.8 82.8 883 38... .8... .8... :trz 2.. 83.8 88.3 82.8 as... .8... 38... HE 2.. 82.3 883 5.... 82.... am ._< 88.3 88.3 8...... 88.... J. «.4 88.3 82.8 888 838 3.9 NS... 2.... 8v... .8 a... 88.3 82.3 82.3 88.3 88.3 8a.... .2... 88.... 82.9 8...... «8.... 2...... ._. =4 8.8.: 83.8 82.8 88.8 83.8 82.: an... :2. 3a... «a... 83 :3 .6 2.3 82.8 82.8 88.3 88.3 82.8 88.8 NS... .8... 88.... 88.... .8... «8... 2.. 5.... 82.3 82.3 823 533 8.8..-. 88.8 2...... n8? 2...? 2...... 2...... 88... .588 5.an 82 It. Erubn 8". IS 82...... fine: .uuohm <2 m< 1.533 .23 3E 33¢. :83— 5u .335 Each—éogtod 0.: mo 82.55 .3 033—. 81 .8828923883282538 3080203.. .0 .3822 u... £280.... 005.05.. 109.com . ad 2.2.9 6.2 2.. .o 2..2 .38.. 818-08 a 25.2.. 2. =2... R. as. .a. 2 .882 .. .2. 2oz . .8. .8. 25 a 8.... 0... 880.0508 .05.. :0 .0 «.30. 005055... 0... 8.8 .8. a... 0.... a :8... 0.8 830.5. 58083.... 05 .0 880.0508 05 8.. 32.0. 0050558 2: a .8... 2.. “2......2 2.2.8.2. 2... . .92 8...“: 2.. a .588... . A833... 0.0 00853.:— am 00.35. 3.300. dd 030,—. 82 the demand equation are all negative and significant. We also reject the third hypothesis that the effect on sales is due to both to a national price change and to a regional demand shift. This is justified by the finding from the second hypothesis that price is not affected by the health-risk information. Models 4 and 5 in Table 4.8 indicate that the retail price of apples in the NYC region was not affected with the initial announcement of the health risk in July 1984. The presence or absence of this risk is measured by Sn- The coefficient estimate of this variable is statistically equal to zero. The retail price remained unaffected with the series of events after February 1989. The added effect after this date is represented by the S2t and/ or the current and the lagged values of the NYTt variable."Ihe estimated coefficients in models 4 and 5 show that both the initial announcement and the subsequent announcements on health risk did not cause any effect on the equilibrium, . price level at the NYC region. After rejecting the first three hypotheses we conclude that the we do not reject the fourth hypothesis which states that the impact on quantity purchased in the NYC region is due only to the demand shift at the regional level. This hypothesis also implies that there is no change in the retail apple price at the NYC region associated with the risk information. This hypothesis suggests that a' =0, 9' <0 and 3: <0. We do not reject this hypothesis because the estimates of the coefficients of all the information variables in the reduced-form equation for price are not significant while they are significant in the reduced-form equation for quantity, i.e., a' = 0 and 7' < 0. The likelihood ratio value that compares model 1 (unrestricted model) to model 6 (restricted model) in Table 4.7 is equal to 13.19. The critical value at the 5 degrees of freedom is 9.24 at the «$0.10 level, 11.07 at the «$0.05 level and 15.09 at the «$0.01 leveLSince this value is greater than the critical value at the 5% and 10% significance levels we conclude 1F or the definitions of the information variables, see Section 2.2 and Table 4.12. 83 that the coefficient estimates of all of the information variables in the reduced-form equation for quantity are significant. In addition to this finding, we already noted in Section 4.4 that the coefficient estimates for the information variables in the demand equation are all negative and significant, i.e., B: <0. In summary, the findings from the reduced-form equations imply that there is no evidence of a price change at the NYC region associated with the risk information. The findings from the reduced-form equations imply that there is a drop in the equilibrium level of per capita purchases in the NYC region and this drop is due only to a demand shift in the NYC region. As outlined in Section 3.1, there are several interpretations which might explain why the price at the NYC region did not change. One reason may be that wholesale prices dropped as a result of a downward shift in wholesale apple demand, but retailers did not adjust apple prices at the retail level. Still another reason may be that there was a commensurate supply shift at the retail apple market such that the retail apple prices remained unaffected. Note that in this research we cannot test which of the above interpretations is true. The findings from the reduced-form equations only tell us that the retail price at the NYC region remained unaffected by the Alar incident. Further research on the effect of the Alar incident at the national market is needed to understand the reason why the regional retail price remained unchanged. We also need additional research to examine the impact of the Alar incident in other regions across the nation. When we examine the other regions, however, we should consider the possibility that the change in the equilibrium quantity in those regions may be associated with both a change in retail price and a downward demand shift at the regional level. In other words, we cannot generalize the result obtained from the NYC region that the retail price was unaffected in the other regions across the nation. 84 4.6 Est' at' theC a e' Revenu to the e' es Emil—era The estimates of the demand equation under alternative specifications of the information variable reported in section 4.4 can be used to estimate the total change in retail apple sales in the NYC region associated with the risk information during the January 1980-July 1989 period. This gives an estimate of the revenue loss to the retailers of fresh apples in the NYC region. The estimate of the revenue loss is the difference between the estimated actual sales and the projected sales that would have occurred had the Alar incident never occurredl. The mathematical derivation to calculate the estimated actual sales, the estimate of sales without the risk effect and the estimate of the lost revenue is presented in Appendix F. The estimates for the actual sales and the projected sales without the Alar controversy were calculated for models 4 and 5 reported in Table 4.5.2 These two models represent the hypothesis that there is a one time, sustained demand shift associated with the initial health-risk information. The consumer continuously updates his/her health-risk perception as he/ she receives additional information on health risk. Figures 4.1 and 4.2 show the projected sales without the Alar incident and the estimated actual sales that are calculated using models 4 and 5. The area under the curve that represents the projected sales without the risk information is the total projected sales without the Alar incident. The area under the curve that represents the estimated actual sales is the total estimated sales with the Alar 1In estimating the change in sales, estimated actual sales rather than the observed values of the sales were used. The reason to use this approach is to minimize the errors is sales loss estimates (see, Mark Smith and others, 1988; Eileen van Ravenswaay and John Hoehn, 1991). 2Since the coefficient estimate of the S variable was not significant, model 5 was reestimated without the 83, when making e sales projections. 85 30 N (1' 1 N o 1 Dollars (Millions) 6? 10---"' O {YTTIIIIITFIIIUUIUIIIIIIIIIIFIIUIIIIIIWUFUIIIIIIIIIIITITIIII 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 Years —- Proi.Soles w/o Alar °°°°° Est.Ac’tual Soles Figure 4.1. Estimates of the Apple Sales in the New York Region With and Without the Risk Information (Model 4) incident. The area between these two curves gives an estimate of the lost revenue to the retailers due to the Alar controversy between the period of July 1984 to June 1989. These estimates are reported in Table 4.9. The results indicate that the Alar incident caused a sales loss of approximately 15% during the July 1984 to June 1989 period. The majority of this sales loss is attributable to the initial announcement on the presence of the risk that is represented by the dummy variable, Sn. According to both of the models, the share of the events in and after February 1989 was relatively small in total revenue loss. In other words, the sales declined around %12 after the initial risk announcement by the EPA an the revenue loss increased as much as to 15% following February 1989. Consistent with the study by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991), the results suggest that the events in and 86 30 25‘ 20‘ 2 2? :2 £15- 8 :2, 10-..'."..:'.. s-. 0 I'I'I'I"1'..111lIIII'U"T""IUI'Ir'UIUIUITTIYVTIIUVIII—11" 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 Years -- Proj.$oles w/o Alar °°°°°° EstAcfuol Soles Figure 4.2. Estimates of the Apple Sales in the New York Region With and Without the Risk Information (Model 5) after February 1989 accounts for a relatively small portion in the total sales loss. Note that we do not know the real reason for the additional shift in demand in February 1989. It can be the intense media coverage on the presence of the risk in and after February 1989 or it can be the release of the revised risk estimates made by the EPA and the NRDC in February 1989. 4.7 The estimates of the change in consumer surplus associated with the risk information can be calculated using the estimated demand curves. The mathematical derivation of 87 Table 4.9. Estimates of Total Apple Sales in the New York Region With and Without the Effect of Alar for the July 1984-June 1989 Period (1983 Dollars) REVENUE ESTIMATES MODEL 4 MODEL 5 1. Projected sales without the risk Information $ 716,816,422 $ 715,139,655 2. Actual estimated sales $ 610,549,321 5 606,971,036 3. Change in sales = (1-2) $ 106,267,321 3 108,168,618 4. % Change in sales = (3/1)‘100 % 14.8 % 15.1 5. Change in sales due to Sn 3 84228450 3 88,343,595 6. Share of S1t in total change in sales =(5/3)*100 % 79.3 % 81.7 7. Change in sales in July 1984- January 1989 period 3 87,713,103 $ 94,676,810 8. Share of July 1984-January 1989 period in total change in % 82.54 % 87.53 sales=(7/3)* 100 9. % Change in sales in July 1984-January 1989 %12.24 %13.24 eriod= 7 1 ’100 the expected value of the consumer surplus with and without the risk information is presented in Appendix G. In order to calculate the expected value of the consumer surplus from an estimated log-linear demand curve, the price elasticity of demand should be greater than one. Otherwise, the value of the consumer surplus and thus its expected value approaches infinity (see Appendix G). The previous research does not reach a consensus as to the ”correct" estimate for the price elasticity of demand for fresh apples at the retail level. It is reported, however, that the demand for apples at the retail level 88 is price elastic both for the studies using annual data and for intraseasonal demand studies.1 The estimated demand curves in this study suggest that apple demand is inelastic at the retail level. This result should be interpreted with caution because of the highly seasonal apple demand and apple price. The observation period covers only 11 years. When the price and quantity variations due to seasonality are taken into account during this time period, there is very little variation left in the price and quantity variations. It is then difficult to estimate a reliable price elasticity. This may explain why the price elasticity estimates reported in this study are so low. Since it is not possible to use the estimated price elasticities from this study to estimate the consumer surplus, the next best alternative is to use the range of own-price elasticity estimates from other studies. The studies that use monthly data have estimated the retail level own-price apple demand elasticities to be between -1.3 and - 4.62. Several values from this range of elasticities were used to calculate the expected value of the change in consumer surplus. The estimates from model 4 and model 5 are virtually identicaL Therefore, the results from model 4 are reported in Table 4.9. The annual change in consumer surplus associated with the information on the presence of the risk due to Alar can be interpreted as the consumer’s annual willingness to pay to avoid health risks due to consuming apples that are treated with Alar.3 Following van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991), dividing annual willingness to pay to avoid health risks due to Alar by the individual’s perceived risk of experiencing the health-problem gives an 1Harry S. Baumes. Jr. and Roger K. Conway. MW; t ERS Staff Report No. AGES850110, 1985 (Washington, DC: Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture). 2See, for example, Henry S. Baumes and Roger K. Conway, 1985; Dana G. Dalymple, "Economic Aspects of Apple Marketing in the United States” (Ph.D. diss., Michigan State University, 1962). 3See the discussion on section 4 of Chapter II. 89 Table 4.10. The Expected Value of the Annual Change in Consumer Surplus Under Alternative Elasticity Estimates (1983 Dollars) a W a Elas- -1.2 -14 -1.6 -1.8 -2.0 -2.2 ticity 19841 2.68 1.35 0.90 0.68 0.55 0.46 1985 6.17 3.11 2.09 1.58 1.27 1.07 1986 7.15 3.49 2.27 1.67 1.30 1.06 1 1987 6.84 3.41 2.26 1.69 1.35 1.12 1988 5.85 2.95 1.98 1.50 1.20 1.10 19892 9.40 4.75 3.21 2.43 1.97 1.66 fl _ l 1 The estimates for the change in consumer surplus represents only the last six months of 1984. The implied change in consumer surplus for this year under the alternative price elasticities are: $5.35 ,$2.69, $1.81, $1.37, $1.13 and $0.92 for own price elasticities of -1.2, -1.4, -1.'6. -1.8, -2.0 and -2.2, respectively. 2 The estimates for the change in consumer surplus represents only the first six months in 1989. The implied change in consumer surplus for this year under the alternative price elasticities are: $18.81, $9.51, $6.41, $4.86, $3.94 and $3.32 for own price elasticities of -1.2, -1.4, -1.6, -1.8, -2.0 and -2.2, respectively. estimate of the marginal willingness to pay for risk reduction. Since the individual’s risk perceptions associated with the consumption of apples that are treated with Alar are not known, the next best alternative is to assume that the individuals believe that the risks are similar to the ones reported in the media. Therefore, these risk levels will be used to estimate the marginal willingness to pay for risk reduction. van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) use a similar approach and employ several alternative assumptions for the 90 risk perception of the consumer.1 Table 4.11 summarizes the individual’s implicit willingness to pay to avoid annual cancer deaths that are calculated by using Model 4. This table replicates the estimates of the implicit willingness to pay that are reported in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). There are two major differences, however. The first difference is that the demand functions in this study are estimated by using a seasonal error structure, rather than an AR(1) specification. The second is that several own price elasticities were used since a reliable elasticity estimate could not be obtained. The implicit willingness to pay to avoid a one in one million risk of cancer death can be compared with the willingness to pay to save a statistical life. The results in Table 4.11 suggest that for a higher range of own price elasticity estimates, the willingness to pay to avoid cancer deaths are very close to the range that are reported in the value of life studies.2 This result is consistent with the findings by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). It implies that the consumers react to risks associated with the consumption of Alar-treated apples consistent with their behavior toward other health-risks, assuming the own price elasticity of apples at the retail level is high and / or that consumer’s risk perceptions were similar to the EPA’s initial risk estimate and the risk estimate by the N RDC. 1The derivation of the annual risk estimates from consuming Alar treated apples are explained in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991). The authors use a linear dose-response model such that the lifetime risk mcrease linearly and can be annualized dividing by individual’s life expectancy (e. g. ., 70 years). It 1s also reported 111 van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) that approximately 17% of the risk from Alar 1n all food sources is due to the consumption of fresh apples. Therefore, the reported health risk 18 multiplied by 0.17 to obtain the health risk associated with the consumption of apples treated with Alar. The authors note that the value of life studies are based on assumptions about perceived mortality risks. The assumptions about perceived risk here are based on risks of getting cancer. The NYT initially reported the risks as cancer death risks but it is not known whether the subsequent cancer risk estimates are equated with mortality risks. Therefore, the implicit willingness to pay estimates for reduced death 1n this study should be treated as rough indicators. 2The willingness to pay to save a statistical life 1s approximately $1.44 to $7. 64 m 1983 Dollars. See van Ravenswaay and Hoehn, 1991; A. Fisher and others, "The Value of Reducing Risks of Death. A Note on New Evidence” W Management 8(1989) PP 83-100 91 Table 4.11. The Implicit Willingness to Pay for an Annual Reduction of One in One Million (1 x 10") Risk of Cancer Death (1983 Dollars) ESTIMATE OF LIFETIME CANCER RISK FROM ALAR= EPA (1985 : 1.7 x 10-5 OWN PRICE ELASTICI- -12 -1.4 -1.6 -1.8 -2.0 -2.2 TIES 1984 22.03 11.08 7.45 5.64 4.65 3.79 1985 25.41 12.81 8.61 6.51 5.23 4.41 1986 29.44 14.37 9.35 6.88 5.35 4.36 1987 28.16 14.04 9.31 6.96 5.56 4.61 1988 24.09 12.15 8.15 6.18 4.94 4.53 1989 77.45 39.16 26.39 20.01 16.22 13.67 ESTIMATE OF LIFETIME CANCER RISK FROM ALAR - NRDC (1989) : 4.1 x 10'5 1984 9.13 4.59 3.09 2.34 1.93 1.57 1985 10.53 5.31 3.57 2.70 2.17 1.83 1986 12.21 5.96 3.88 2.85 2.22 1.81 1987 11.68 5.82 3.86 2.89 2.30 1.91 1988 9.99 5.04 3.38 2.56 2.05 1.88 1989 32.11 16.24 10.94 8.30 6.73 5.67 I ESTIMATE OF LIFETIME CANCER RISK FROM ALAR= - EPA (1989) : 6.0 x 1045 1984 62.42 31.38 21.12 15.98 13.18 10.73 1985 71.98 36.28 24.38 18.43 14.82 12.48 1986 83.42 40.72 26.48 19.48 15.17 12.37 26.37 19.72 23.10 17.50 74.78 56.70 92 Table 4.12. Definitions of the Variables Used in the Econometric Model VARIABLES pqt Peflated retail price of apples in the NYC market at time py, Peflated retail price of bananas in the NYC market at time m, Per capita deflated earnings in the NYC market at time t. h, National apple storage holdings at time t. S1t Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 between July 1984 throuthune 1989 and 0 otherwise. 521 Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 between February 1989 through June 1989 and 0 otherwise. S3t Dummy variable that takes the value of 1 after June 1989 through July 1991 and 0 otherwise. CNYT, Cumulative number of articles in the New York Times on the presence of health risk associated with Alar at time t. NYTt Number of articles in the New York Times on the presence of health risk associated with Alar at time t-1. NYTm One period lagged value of NYT,. NYTQ Two period lagged value of NYT” NYTM Three period lagged value of NYT,. MA Moving average term. AR Autoregfissive term. MA(Seas) Seasonal moving average term. CHAPTER V CONCLUSIONS, POLICY ISSUES, AND FURTHER RESEARCH 5.1 u a of Research oble C! et 0 This research investigated how food purchases are affected when consumers receive information on the existence of a health-risk associated with the consumption of a particular food. More specifically, it examined the effect of the Alar scare on retail fresh apple purchases in the NYC region. The observation period was January 1980 through July 1991. Having data on apple purchases two years after the date Alar was withdrawn from the market allowed us to examine whether the Alar controversy had a long-term effect on apple demand in the NYC region. In answering this research question, Chapter II developed a conceptual model of consumption that incorporates the health-risk information in a demand function. The information variables that would measure the risk were then identified and the hypotheses specifying the impact of changes in health-risk information on food purchases were developed. Chapter III defined the econometric model for apple . demand and derived the reduced-form equations for quantity and price. The methods to empirically estimate the demand equation and the reduced-form equations were presented. Chapter IV reported the empirical findings of the research. The following sections in this Chapter summarize the empirical results of the study that are reported in Chapter IV and derive policy implications. Further research needs stemming from this research are identified later in the Chapter. 93 94 5.2 Summagy of the Research Results 5.2.1 The Importance of Considering Seasonalig when gtimatm' g the Regression Equation This research demonstrates that seasonal variation in variables, such as the variable that measures the per capita apple purchases in the NYC apple demand model, must be taken into account in estimating a time-series econometric model. If we do not correct for seasonality, we do not know whether the variation in the dependent variable is due to the seasonal variation or to the variations in the nonseasonal factors. The seasonal variation is specified by a seasonal ARMA model and the variations associated with the nonseasonal factors are explained by the exogenous variables in the demand model. In order to determine how the seasonal error specification affects the demand- equation estimates and thus the coefficient estimates for the information variables, the demand model reported in van Ravenswaay and Hoehn was reestimated using a seasonal error structure. It was found that with a seasonal error structure, the information variables do not provide any additional explanatory power to the equation estimate at the 1% and 5% significance levels in the January 1980-July 1989 observation period and they are significant only at the 10% significance level. Without the seasonal component in the equation for the same observation period, however, the information variables were jointly significant at both the 5% and 10% significance levels.l The Q-statistic, which tests the overall acceptability of the residual autocorrelations, suggests that for the AR( 1) specification the serial correlation in the demand model was not yet eliminated. When we specify a seasonal error structure, the O-statistic suggests that the serial correlation in lEileen van Ravenswaay and John Hoehn, 1991. 95 the model was eliminated. This implies that the seasonal ARMA model is the correct specification when compared to the AR(1) model. Since with the seasonal error specification we are able to reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients for all of the information variables are equal to zero only at the 10% significance level but not at the 5% and 1% significance levels, it is not certain whether the Alar incident caused a downward shift in apple demand in the NYC region at all When the observation period was extended two years beyond the removal of Alar from the market, we found that the information effect on the quantity demanded was significant with the seasonal model at the 5% and 10% significance levels. This implies that there is a stronger evidence of the impact of Alar on apple demand in NYC region with the extended observation period. This may mean that a longer observation period added more precision to the demand equation estimate. 5.2.2 W190 The results from the tests for simultaneity bias in the NYC demand equation confirm that the price variable and the error term are not correlated. This finding implies that simultaneity bias is not an issue in analyzing the impact of health-risk information in the regional market such as the NYC market when the incident actually covers the whole nation. The findings from the reduced-form equations for the NYC retail apple price also support this finding In the reduced-form equation for price, we found that risk information at the national level does not affect the NYC region’s retail apple prices. One possible reason why the NYC retail price did not change may be that there was an offsetting supply shift at the national retail market for apples such that the retail price of apples in the national retail market and thus at the regional retail markets was not affected by the risk information. Another reason may be that the national wholesale 96 price may drop as a result of a demand shift in the national wholesale market but the regional retailers do not change their prices. We do not know which of the above interpretations is true in explaining the reason why the NYC retail price did not change. To find out which interpretation is true, further research is needed to examine what happened to quantity and price of apples at the national wholesale and the retail apple markets as a result of information on Alar. 52-3 Infcunati90§ff99t Consumers Show a swift and systematic response when they are informed about the presence or absence of the reported risk in the market. Consistent with the findings by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991), the effect of the Alar incident in the NYC region started in July 1984, when the EPA first announced the potential health effects associated with the lifetime consumption of Alar-treated apples. The findings show that consumers update their risk perceptions as they receive additional information on health risk In other words, the events in and after February 1989 caused an additional shift in apple demand. Note that with the available data, we are not able to distinguish the real cause of the additional shift in demand. It could have been the presence of the revised risk estimates released by the EPA and the NRDC or it could have been the intense media coverage. Both of these two incidents happened between February 1989 to June 1989. The variable that measures the presence or absence of the revised risk estimates ($2,) is closely correlated with the current and one period lagged value of the variable that measures the intensity of the reporting (NYTt). There is not sufficient information that will enable us to differentiate between the impact of these two variables on the per capita apple purchases. If the period during which there was intense media coverage did not overlap with the period during which the revise estimates were released, it would 97 have been possible to estimate the separate effects of the intense media coverage and the release of new risk estimates on the per capita apple purchases. 5.2.4 Own-Brice Elastigities The price elasticity of apple demand was estimated to be less than one. This estimated own-price elasticity is smaller than that estimated by previous research.1 An inelastic own-price elasticity estimate may be a result of the variations in apple price and apple purchases being explained by the seasonality in the demand model. When we account for seasonality in the demand model, there is little variation left to estimate a reliable own-price elasticity figure. A longer time series would allow us to estimate a more reliable own-price elasticity. The apple sales at the retail market in the NYC market would have been 15% higher had the Alar event never occurred. This implies that a drop in apple sales of almost $100 million was realized in the NYC region during the June 1984-July 1989 period. About 80% of this drop in apples sales is attributable to a one-time and persistent demand shift associated with the initial announcement made by the EPA that Alar was a potential carcinogen. 1See, Henry S. Baumes and Roger K. Conway, 1985. 98 5.2.6 ha e ' ons er lus ss 'ated wit pormatio on Since it was not possible to estimate a reliable price elasticity of demand, several different assumptions on the price elasticity had to be made in order to calculate the change in expected consumer surplus. Following previous research1 the assumed own- price elasticity was between -1.3 to -4.6. It was found that as the assumption on the magnitude of the price elasticity was increased, the change in the expected consumer surplus became increasingly smaller. Following the discussion in Section 4 of Chapter H, the change in expected consumer surplus can be approximated to represent the consumer’s willingness to pay to avoid Alar residues. If we assume that the consumer’s perceived risk is similar to the risks reported in the media, it is possible to infer the implicit willingness to pay for an annual reduction of one in one million risk of cancer death. For higher own-price elasticity estimates (-1.8 to -2.2), the implicit willingness to pay to avoid cancer deaths was close to the range that was reported in value of life studies. Following van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991), it should be noted that the implicit willingness to pay estimates in this research are based on very restrictive assumptions on the risk perceptions of consumers.2 5.3 1191mm This research shows that consumers respond immediately once they are informed on the presence or absence of the reported risk in the market. Sales of apples drop even further as consumers receive additional information on health risk. This result has important implications for policy makers making decisions in the presence of health- 1Henry S. Baumes and Roger K. Conway, 1985; Dana G. Dalymple, 1962. 2See Section 4.7. 99 scare events such as the Alar incident. Since many of the older pesticides currently used have not yet been fully tested for toxicity, it is likely that as new toxicity estimates are released, conflicts similar to the Alar controversy will arise. Consumers are likely to shift away from foods that contain residues of toxic substances. In order to minimize the revenue losses to the food industry, the government could recall the suspected chemical as soon as the initial reporting of the toxicity of a substance is released. In the Alar controversy, for example, the drop in apple demand that took place between July 1984 to June 1989 could have been avoided had the Government recalled the existing quantities and suspended the sale of Alar in July 1984 while it continued the toxicity studies. An alternative policy option for the Government could have been not announcing the preliminary findings of the toxicity studies until a consensus was reached regarding health risks associated with Alar. Still another policy could be that the interest goups releasing statements about risks prior to definitive government study be subject to product disparagement suits. We would not know which policy option is the most feasible to implement unless we estimate the benefits and costs associated with each policy alternative. The estimate of the risk reduction benefits from this study provides information on the benefits of a policy that would eliminate health risks associated with Alar. The findings of this study indicate that the consumers are willing to pay amounts of money that are consistent with the previous literature on the value of life, i.e., between the range of $1.44 and $7.64 in 1983 dollars.l This result implies that in similar health scare incidents in the future, if the costs of a policy such as product recalling that would eliminate health risks from the chemical are smaller than this estimated range, the Government should implement that policy option. 1We note in Section 4.7 that the estimate of the benefits from avoiding risks from Alar is based on very restrictive assumptions about risk perceptions and we assume that own price elasticity of apples are high. 100 The food industry might also learn from the findings of this study. In the future, when conflicts similar to the Alar incident arise, in order to minimize the revenue losses the food industry may announce that they voluntarily stop using the chemical right after the chemical is announced to be harmful to human health. The food industry may therefore minimize likely conflicts. Alternatively, the food industry may direct its policies to ask Government to recall the chemical or not to announce the preliminary findings until the toxicity studies are finalized. 5.4 fo u e r The findings of this research suggest that the Alar controversy affected the apple demand in the NYC market. The research should be duplieated to other markets to test whether the Alar incident had the same effect across the nation. 'We also find in this research that the problem of simultaneity bias is not an issue in analyzing the effect of the information on Alar in apple demand in a regional retail market using a single equation model. This means that there was no evidence of a price change associated with the Alar incident at the NYC region. The reason why the retail apple price at the NYC region did not change can be interpreted in several ways.1 The finding that the price at the NYC level did not change with the Alar incident could not be generalized to the other markets at the nation unless we find that the price at the other regions remained unaffected. Further research is needed to examine the other regions across the nation. Another way to support the results obtained from this research is to examine the effect of the Alar controversy in the national retail apple market. Examining the effect of health-risk information at the national retail market using a simultaneous supply and demand model may strengthen the finding of this study 1See the discussion in Section 3.1. 101 if we find that the retail price at the national market was not affected by the Alar controversy. This would confirm that we need not worry about the simultaneity bias when estimating apple demand in a regional market by a single equation, when the event actually covers the whole nation. The effect of the Alar incident on the processed apple market could also be explored in further research. A downward shift in processed apple demand would also be expected associated with the reports in the media on the toxicity of UDMH, a derivative of Alar which is found in processed apple products. APPENDIX A DESCRIPTION OF DATA APPENDIX A DESCRIPTION OF DATA The data consist of monthly observations of apple purchases, population, retail prices of fresh apples and bananas, consumer price index, disposable income, number of articles on the presence of Alar reported in the New York Times (NYT) and the national fresh apple holdings. As stated in Section 1.7 of Chapter I, the data used in this study is largely identical to the one reported in Guyton (1990). The difference in the two data sets is related with the definition of the population area in the NYC market and we include variables on income and national fresh apple storage holdings to the model. Data described below is reported in Appendix 3.1 TOTAL FRESH APPLE PURCHASES: Monthly data on fresh apple purchases consist of the arrivals of fresh apples to the NYC market reported by the United States Department of Agiculture (USDA).2 POPULATION: The population figures in this study cover a smaller area than the ones reported in Guyton. This is because the monthly arrivals of apples for fresh consumption to the New York-Newark metropolitan area covers five Primary Metropolitan Statistical Areas (PMSA) in the New York-Northern New Jersey, Long Island Consolidated Metropolitan Statistical Area (CMSA). These PMSAs are, Bergen- 1F or a detailed description of data on total fresh apple purchases, retail prices of apples and bananas and articles on the presence of Alar reported in the NYT, see, William P. Guyton, 1990. 2U.S. Department of Agiculture, Agicultural Marketing Service, ' We. Washington. DC. Jammy 1980 - July 1991- 102 103 Passaic, Jersey City, Nassau-Suffolk, New York and N ewark.1 The population figures that are reported in Guyton cover the whole CMSA. Since only annual population figures were available, the monthly figures were derived from the annual data by using the following formula that demonstrates as an example of the calculation procedure for the monthly gowth rate between 1981 and 1982: 1981 population estimate(1+r)‘2=l982 population estimate where r is the monthly population gowth rate and 12 denotes the number of months between two annual observations. Since we have the 1981 and 1982 population estimates that are reported in July of 1981 and 1982, we can solve for r and then use this gowth rate to calculate the monthly population rate. Similar procedure was used to calculate the monthly population figures for each year. The 1989 population estimate was not available since the population estimates are usually not released for the years before the census year. Therefore, the population figures for the months between July 1988 and April 1990 were calculated in the similar way for the 21 months as described in the example above. Note that for the census years (1980 and 1990) the p0pulation figures were released in April and for the remaining years the population figures were released in July. The population estimate for 1991 was not yet released. Therefore, the projection for the months after the 1990 population figure was based on the gowth rate from April 1980 to April 1990 by using the following formula: ’ 1The population estimates are not reported 10 the years before the census, i. e., 1979 and 1989. The population estimate for the years of census are reported' In April and for all other years they are reported In July. Annual population data for 1978;1988 were obtained fron U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Rm Series P25, 1978- 1988. The population for 1990 was obtained froem U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, WW 911mm CPH-l 1990 104 1980 population estimatea +r)“°=1990 population estimate The gowth rate is calculated by solving for r. This figure was multiplied by the population estimate in 1990 and then added to the 1990 population estimate to get the subsequent month’s figure. This procedure was repeated until July 1991’s population estimate was obtained. FRESH APPLE AND BANANA PRICES: Prices of fresh apples and bananas were obtained from the monthly market basket reports published by the NYC Department of Consumer Affairs.1 Both prices were deflated by the consumer price index for all urban consumers (CPI-U) for the New York City-Newark Metropolitan Area. We chose bananas to be a substitute for fresh apples in the demand model because bananas were the only fruit whose prices were reported in the NYC Market Basket Reports. Guyton (1991) reports that oranges may be used as another substitute for fresh apples. He incorporated a variable that measures the regional deflated retail prices of oranges. However, the coefficient for the orange price variable yielded a negative Sign. He therefore dropped the orange price variable. The possibility of incorporating the prices of other fresh fruits was therefore restricted. For example, we wanted to incorporate a variable that measures the availability of specialty fruits in the market. The reason to have such a variable in the model is to be able to account for the increasing availability of such fruits which may cause consumers to shift away from consuming apples.2 However, since the retail price of such fruits were not reported, the option of constructing such a variable was dropped. 1New York City of Consumer Affairs, MW New York, January 1980 July 1991. ”USDA, Agricultural Marketing Service W309 W Washington, D. C, January 1980- -July 1991. 105 INCOME: A proxy to represent the personal income variable was sought. The closest variable that would measure the personal income with no seasonal adjustment across the months were the earning data that are reported monthly by The State of New York, Department of Labor.1 The Department of Labor reports the number of employees and weekly earning in nonagicultural establishments by industry in New York City. The industries for which both the number of employees and weekly earnings are, manufacturing, construction, telephone and telegam, electric gas and sanitary services, and wholesale trade. The total weekly earning were calculated by multiplying the number of employees in that industry with the average weekly earning in each industry. The average total weekly earning was obtained by dividing the total weekly earnings by the total number of employees in the five industries. The average weekly earnings was expressed in 1983 dollars through dividing by the NYC consumer price index for all urban consumers (CPI-U). Deflated average monthly earnings was obtained by multiplying the deflated weekly average earning with the number of weeks in each month. The data that are used to calculate the monthly earnings is reported in Appendix C. APPLE HOLDINGS: Another variable that was not used in the study by van Ravenswaay and Hoehn (1991) but was included in this research is the national fresh apple holding. The variable that represents the monthly national fresh apple holdings was obtained from the International Apple Institute.2 The data involves the total fresh apple holdings of all varieties in cold storage and controlled atmosphere excluding the processor’s holding. 1State of New York, Department of Labor, W New York, January 1980 - July 1991. ’International Apple Industry. WWW Mc Lean. Virginia, January 1980 - July 1991. 106 National fresh apple holdings were used as one explanatory variable in the national retail apple supply equation in the econometric model. The data represent holding at the wholesale level. Apples are stored when they are at the wholesale market. There are three types of storage facilities: common storage, cold storage and controlled atmosphere storage.1 The supply of fresh apples from wholesale market to retail market and thus from retail market to consumer is determined by the quantity of fresh apple holding at the wholesale market. Therefore, a variable that measures the quantity of fresh apple holding at the wholesale market was incorporated in the retail apple supply equation. Note that in July - October, the holding are reported to be zero. The reason for this is that since the holding are very small at those months, the International Apple Institute does not report apple holding these months. In the econometric model the logarithms of the holding variable were used. Therefore we add 1 to the variable that measures holding (HOLD) in order to gat a variable in logarithms (lnht = ln(HOLD + 1)). ’ AR’ITCLES ON THE PRESENCE OF ALAR: Following Guyton (1990), since the NYT had the largest circulation size, we chose this newspaper as a proxy for the newspaper coverage on Alar. Using the "Alar” and 'Daminozide" keywords, a search of the full text of the NYT article from the Nexis data base of the full text of the NYT articles from January 1980-July 1991 was performed. Figure A.1 shows the per capita apple consumption and retail price of apples in the NYC region for the extended observation period. 1John Mark Halloran, " Price Forecasting Model for Michigan Fresh Apples." MS. Thesis, Michigan State University, 1981, pp.22-23. 107 in ooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo d O"! n oooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo 1:. I 1’: 0.6 +--- Dollars or Pounds ooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooooo F’ .1; l 0.2 .. .............................................................................................. O- 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 Years -- PC Apple Cons. --...- Retail Apple Pr. Figure A.l. Retail Fresh Apple Prices (1983 Dollars) and Per Capita Fresh Apple Purchases in the NYC Region (Pounds) APPENDIX B THE DATA 1980 1981 1982 1983 MONTHS Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. .APPENLHXIB TTHEIMYDA QNY‘ 18,900,000 19,600,000 19,800,000 15,000,000 15,200,000 13,200,000 8,300,000 4,700,000 10,300,000 20,100,000 18,100,000 22,000,000 24,800,000 24,600,000 23,700,000 17,500,000 17,200,000 11,900,000 9,200,000 10,200,000 11,300,000 17,700,000 25,800,000 21,200,000 16,100,000 19,900,000 22,100,000 19,100,000 21,900,000 13,600,000 7,700,000 7,800,000 7,900,000 13,700,000 17,400,000 18,500,000 14,400,000 18,700,000 KB POPNYZ 14,645,742 14,633,820 14,621,909 14,610,000 14,610,999 14,611,999 14,612,998 14,613,998 14,614,997 14,615,997 14,616,997 14,617,997 14,618,996 14,619,996 14,620,996 14,621,996 14,622,997 14,623,997 14,625,000 14,626,416 14,627,832 14,629,248 14,630,664 14,632,080 14,633,496 14,634,913 14,636,329 14,637,746 14,639,163 14,640,580 14,642,000 14,645,246 14,648,493 14,651,741 14,654,989 14,658,238 14,661,488 14,664,738 PCQNY3 1.290477 1.339363 1.354132 1.026694 1.040312 0.903367 0.567987 0.321609 0.704756 1.375206 1.238284 1.504994 1.696423 1.682627 1.620957 1.196827 1.176230 0.813731 0.629060 0.697368 0.772500 1.209905 1.763420 1.448871 1.100216 1.359762 1.509941 1.304846 1.495987 0.928925 0.525884 0.532596 0.539305 0.935042 1.187309 1.262089 0.982165 1.275168 1984 1985 1986 1987 Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July 109 21,300,000 19,600,000 18,000,000 13,500,000 9,400,000 7,300,000 10,300,000 15,700,000 23,700,000 16,000,000 18,600,000 18,200,000 19,300,000 15,400,000 15,500,000 8,500,000 6,600,000 6,900,000 7,200,000 11,000,000 14,800,000 11,800,000 12,900,000 12,700,000 14,300,000 16,000,000 15,000,000 8,300,000 7,100,000 5,900,000 7,000,000 11,800,000 13,700,000 14,900,000 13,200,000 13,400,000 13,400,000 13,500,000 10,700,000 6,500,000 4,100,000 2,100,000 9,500,000 18,700,000 14,700,000 20,100,000 10,700,000 8,500,000 14,900,000 11,200,000 9,600,000 17,500,000 15,000,000 14,667,989 14,671,241 14,674,494 14,677,747 14,681,000 14,687,981 14,694,965 14,701,952 14,708,943 14,715,937 14,722,935 14,729,935 14,736,940 14,743,947 14,750,958 14,757,972 14,765,000 14,772,230 14,779,464 14,786,702 14,793,943 14,801,188 14,808,436 14,815,687 14,822,943 14,830,201 14,837,464 14,844,730 14,852,000 14,851,667 14,851,333 14,851,000 14,850,667 14,850,333 14,850,000 14,849,667 14,849,333 14,849,000 14,848,667 14,848,333 14,848,000 14,851,662 14,855,324 14,858,987 14,862,651 14,866,317 14,869,983 14,873,650 14,877,317 14,880,986 14,884,656 14,888,326 14,892,000 1.452142 1.335947 1.226618 0.919760 0.640283 0.497005 0.700920 1.067885 1.611265 1.087257 1.263335 1.235579 1.309634 1.044496 1.050779 0.575960 0.447003 0.467093 0.487162 0.743912 1.000409 0.797233 0.871125 0.857200 0.964721 1.078879 1.010954 0.559121 0.478050 0.397262 0.471338 0.794559 0.922518 1.003344 0.888889 0.902377 0.902397 0.909152 0.720603 0.437760 0.276131 0.141398 0.639501 1.258498 0.989056 1.352050 0.719570 0.571480 1.001525 0.752638 0.644959 1.175418 1.007252 1988 1989 1990 1991 Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July 110 7,800,000 8,400,000 15,700,000 13,200,000 12,000,000 16,700,000 16,400,000 16,000,000 15,400,000 11,900,000 8,900,000 8,100,000 6,300,000 6,200,000 8,600,000 9,800,000 9,700,000 9,100,000 9,800,000 10,300,000 8,100,000 8,800,000 7,000,000 9,400,000 9,800,000 10,600,000 8,500,000 10,900,000 14,300,000 13,100,000 11,100,000 17,200,000 15,300,000 12,100,000 12,700,000 10,100,000 9,500,000 6,800,000 12,400,000 12,500,000 11,700,000 12,100,000 13,100,000 12,200,000 12,500,000 12,600,000 10,700,000 10,100,000 14,894,829 14,897,659 14,900,490 14,903,321 14,906,153 14,908,985 14,911,818 14,914,651 14,917,485 14,920,319 14,923,154 14,926,000 14,920,504 14,915,011 14,909,519 14,904,029 14,898,541 14,893,056 14,887,572 14,882,091 14,876,611 14,871,133 14,865,658 14,860,184 14,854,713 14,849,243 14,843,776 14,838,310 14,832,847 14,827,385 14,821,926 14,816,469 14,811,000 14,812,687 14,814,374 14,816,061 14,817,749 14,819,437 14,821,125 14,822,813 14,824,501 14,826,190 14,827,878 14,829,567 14,831,256 14,832,946 14,834,635 14,836,325 1. Fresh apple purchases in the NYC region (pounds). 0.523672 0.563847 1.053657 0.885709 0.805037 1.120130 1.099799 1.072771 1.032346 0.797570 0.596389 0.542677 0.422238 0.415689 0.576813 0.657540 0.651070 0.611023 0.658267 0.692107 0.544479 0.591750 0.470884 0.632563 0.659723 0.713841 0.572631 0.734585 0.964077 0.883500 0.748891 1.160870 1.033016 0.816867 0.857276 0.681693 0.641123 0.458857 0.836644 0.843295 0.789234 0.816123 0.883471 0.822681 0.842815 0.849460 0.721285 0.680762 1 11 2.NYC population. 3.Per capita apple purchases in the NYC region (QNY/POPNY). 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 MONTHS Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. 112 DRPANY‘ 0.728900 0.760456 0.787500 0.818859 0.838471 0.852619 0.883777 0.996399 0.933014 0.713436 0.673759 0.678363 0.637312 0.640732 0.660592 0.656852 0.641892 0.681564 0.715859 0.796943 0.763441 0.679612 0.680346 0.679612 0.678149 0.676692 0.745946 0.700431 0.725720 0.721003 0.761210 0.737279 0.710608 0.660569 0.652396 0.656410 0.644172 0.622449 0.621814 0.615540 0.623742 0.661986 0.700000 0.729271 0.772277 0.651530 0.648968 0.648330 0.642023 0.628627 0.626808 0.691643 DRPBNY5 0.409207 0.456274 0.475000 0.459057 0.468557 0.426309 0.411622 0.432173 0.430622 0.404281 0.413712 0.421053 0.428737 0.423341 0.444191 0.430351 0.450450 0.413408 0.396476 0.393013 0.419355 0.399137 0.399568 0.399137 0.409042 0.397422 0.421622 0.431034 0.405550 0.397074 0.354536 0.353063 0.370752 0.335366 0.346585 0.338462 0.378323 0.377551 0.377166 0.454087 0.482897 0.471414 0.450000 0.439560 0.425743 0.394867 0.363815 0.353635 0.359922 0.377176 0.366442 0.384246 CPINY‘ 0.782 0.789 0.800 0.806 0.811 0.821 0.826 0.833 0.836 0.841 0.846 0.855 0.863 0.874 0.878 0.883 0.888 0.895 0.908 0.916 0.930 0.927 0.926 0.927 0.929 0.931 0.925 0.928 0.937 0.957 0.959 0.963 0.971 0.984 0.981 0.975 0.978 0.980 0.981 0.991 0.994 0.997 1.000 1.001 1.010 1.013 1.017 1.018 1.028 1.034 1.037 1.041 1985 1986 1987 1988 May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. NB 0.691643 0.699904 0.696565 0.710900 0.725047 0.725730 0.629108 0.657277 0.609185 0.643057 0.679070 0.658017 0.638298 0.683287 0.710332 0.677656 0.729927 0.673953 0.623306 0.639640 0.724508 0.735426 0.735426 0.746403 0.775473 0.823635 0.826667 1.029281 1.000000 0.749559 0.750221 0.711775 0.706190 0.711188 0.708117 0.720412 0.852515 0.780985 0.814249 0.782170 0.742905 0.623960 0.564315 0.563847 0.623330 0.660125 0.633745 0.611746 0.619397 0.641755 0.736246 0.909823 0.896825 0.374640 0.383509 0.381679 0.369668 0.329567 0.367578 0.309859 0.328638 0.365511 0.382106 0.390698 0.417053 0.388529 0.378578 0.359779 0.357143 0.374088 0.346084 0.316170 0.396396 0.357782 0.367713 0.376682 0.458633 0.477908 0.384960 0.355556 0.346051 0.362832 0.361552 0.370697 0.333919 0.348736 0.364267 0.371330 0.351630 0.383632 0.373514 0.347752 0.336417 0.358932 0.332779 0.340249 0.339967 0.356189 0.401427 0.370370 0.358891 0.374898 0.446791 0.380259 0.338164 0.341270 1.041 1.043 1.048 1.055 1.062 1.061 1.065 1.065 1.067 1.073 1.075 1.079 1.081 1.083 1.084 1.092 1.096 1.098 1.107 1.110 1.118 1.115 1.115 1.112 1.109 1.117 1.125 1.127 1.130 1.134 1.133 1.138 1.147 1.153 1.158 1.166 1.173 1.178 1.179 1.189 1.198 1.202 1.205 1.206 1.123 1.121 1.215 1.226 1.227 1.231 1.236 1.242 1.260 UM Oct. 0.649762 0.340729 1.262 NOV. 0.611597 0.357427 1.259 Dec. 0.619048 0.365079 1.260 1989 Jan. 0.629921 0.346457 1.270 Feb. 0.650470 0.352665 1.276 Mar. 0.636152 0.403413 1.289 Apr. 0.594595 0.440154 1.295 May 0.591398 0.460829 1.302 June 0.605364 0.413793 1.305 July 0.604900 0.367534 1.306 Aug. 0.649351 0.366692 1.309 Sep. 0.605144 0.363086 1.322 Oct. 0.549699 0.384036 1.328 NOV. 0.525526 0.360360 1.332 Dec. 0.525131 0.360090 1.333 1990 Jan. 0.525537 0.399704 1.351 Feb. 0.569106 0.428677 1.353 Mar. 0.571010 0.409956 1.366 Apr. 0.568099 0.393299 1.373 May 0.575802 0.393586 1.372 June 0.598104 0.364697 1.371 July 0.628613 0.440751 1.384 Aug. 0.685714 0.385714 1.400 Sep. 0.681818 0.383523 1.408 Oct. 0.600282 0.360169 1.416 NOV. 0.579505 0.360424 1.415 Dec. 0.593220 0.360169 1.416 1991 Jan. 0.622378 0.370629 1.430 Feb. 0.640669 0.376045 1.436 Mar. 0.641562 0.446304 1.434 Apr. 0.661100 0.424495 1.437 May 0.694444 0.451389 1.440 June 0.726141 0.421853 1.446 July 0.750689 0.385675 1.452 4.Deflated retail apple price in the NYC region (1983 dollars). 5.Deflated retail banana price in the NYC region (1983 dollars). 6.Consumer price index in the NYC region for all items. 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 MONTHS Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. U6 INCOME7 1578.634 1476.705 1551.665 1474.719 1526.071 1477.181 1532.385 1515.234 1474.841 1542.238 1522.024 1574.549 1570.320 1400.637 1561.691 1494.169 1539.756 1481.312 1515.616 1528.019 1463.309 1540.839 1516.792 1583.651 1581.489 1388.502 1604.991 1527.768 1583.073 1516.135 1563.020 1570.380 1518.425 1568.507 1568.832 1662.004 1643.152 1453.454 1626.420 1567.737 1615.443 1569.354 1617.066 1514.769 1567.353 1644.196 1631.270 1688.571 1641.401 1525.934 1605.585 1581.505 HOLD8 49,868,000 39,613,000 30,095,000 20,564,000 13,042,000 6,240,000 0 0 0 0 89,392,000 77,355,000 63,066,000 51,904,000 40,676,000 30,190,000 20,497,000 12,057,000 0 0 0 0 71,452,000 60,775,000 49,363,000 40,059,000 31,689,000 23,233,000 15,507,000 9,294,000 0 0 0 0 79,833,000 69,116,000 58,092,000 47,807,000 38,169,000 27,063,000 17,254,000 9,743,000 0 0 0 0 76,283,000 68,390,000 56,534,000 45,410,000 36,336,000 26,613,000 2 K1 0'3 0 OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 1985 1986 1987 1988 May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. 116 1631.301 1584.119 1635.834 1626.068 1592.595 1665.451 1636.418 1718.671 1672.560 1516.377 1667.883 1599.447 1669.996 1631.009 1696.756 1676.381 1647.302 1694.433 1682.624 1751.948 1715.945 1532.789 1719.671 1668.059 1742.229 1678.300 1724.353 1689.381 1691.428 1725.194 1727.925 1789.157 1762.128 1543.497 1730.284 1664.993 1740.462 1691.758 1763.116 1735.950 1692.276 1737.629 1715.832 1759.852 1846.423 1728.918 1741.795 1656.813 1721.739 1669.664 1729.196 1707.874 1643.642 17,884,000 10,349,000 0 0 0 0 76,680,000 68,295,000 56,450,000 45,997,000 35,751,000 26,865,000 17,832,000 10,839,000 0 0 0 0 69,153,000 59,239,000 47,907,000 37,639,000 28,523,000 19,800,000 11,642,000 5,889,000 0 0 0 0 77,452,000 65,529,000 52,849,000 42,499,000 32,524,000 23,049,000 14,484,000 8,274,000 0 0 0 0 96,453,000 81,291,000 67,832,000 55,176,000 42,897,000 29,700,000 19,180,000 10,614,000 0 0 0 HOOOOOHHOOOHI—‘OOHNOOOUOHOOONHNOl-‘ONOOOHNOOOOOOOOOOOOHOO 1989 1990 1991 Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July 117 1721.664 1698.880 1760.965 1711.916 1532.095 1707.559 1664.113 1684.681 1640.445 1692.289 1675.431 1633.923 1681.306 1654.425 1714.878 1655.626 1503.807 1551.338 1567.521 1660.109 1610.297 1650.857 1522.613 1586.543 1521.130 1482.130 1462.946 1610.991 1455.881 1612.496 1556.808 1606.141 1552.139 1583.827 0 87,027,000 73,754,000 61,161,000 50,372,000 39,433,000 29,730,000 21,397,000 13,673,000 0 0 0 0 102,000,000 86,341,000 71,382,000 57,629,000 46,366,000 33,852,000 23,137,000 14,027,000 0 0 0 0 87,827,000 74,361,000 62,877,000 50,479,000 39,553,000 29,361,000 20,278,000 13,378,000 0 7.The derivation of the income variable is explained in Appendix C. 8.National fresh apple holdings (bushels). 9.Number of articles in the New York Times on the presence of health risk associated with Alar. N 1.1 OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOONU‘O\ll-‘OOO APPENDIX C WEEKLY DATA ON EARNINGS 1980 1981 1982 1983 MONTHS Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. AXPPETH)EK(3 nasal 492,600 503,700 508,900 493,000 501,400 503,000 480,900 492,400 496,800 497,800 494,400 483,500 469,900 482,700 488,600 488,500 491,300 496,000 478,900 489,400 495,700 487,500 483,600 469,500 452,800 642,600 466,000 455,000 456,700 459,200 438,800 449,100 453,000 445,800 440,300 430,500 417,200 426,100 432,300 430,300 MAWERZ. 229.40 232.63 233.25 227.76 231.25 234.47 234.33 234.15 234.21 239.85 245.23 250.21 249.75 250.43 254.25 253.27 253.57 254.76 253.46 252.50 255.76 259.78 263.75 267.81 265.36 268.28 271.57 265.72 267.91 269.37 270.03 267.89 270.05 275.15 282.96 287.36 283.75 278.17 284.34 287.73 118 WEEKLY DATA ON EARNINGS coau3 71,400 70,500 72,100 73,300 76,000 78,000 79,100 79,400 80,200 80,800 80,800 80,400 75,500 76,700 78,900 80,800 82,200 84,100 84,400 85,400 86,000 86,200 85,200 85,100 79,900 79,300 82,400 84,100 86,600 88,500 85,300 86,000 87,900 87,900 88,500 87,900 81,900 81,100 83,600 86,800 cowaR‘ 393.54 396.89 396.23 394.28 400.58 412.62 421.11 418.74 421.61 409.52 424.45 436.93 438.70 416.29 447.58 446.40 441.77 452.45 445.42 465.26 455.70 444.04 455.68 470.02 469.22 449.88 479.82 467.82 488.07 499.85 490.10 499.37 504.75 499.73 525.62 531.80 536.51 527.95 535.36 542.36 1984 1985 1986 1987 432,900 439,000 421,400 435,600 441,900 441,800 441,800 432,800 420,700 431,600 437,800 431,700 433,100 436,300 420,300 432,200 435,700 429,200 427,300 419,100 403,800 411,900 416,100 407,600 410,100 411,700 398,700 407,200 410,100 407,200 408,300 399,600 388,600 395,600 399,000 392,500 392,000 392,800 383,500 390,700 395,100 393,100 390,900 384,000 370,000 378,400 384,100 377,700 379,800 382,600 373,200 380,800 384,900 119 289.25 291.19 289.38 286.04 291.40 298.34 300.58 303.62 299.02 299.84 298.74 302.29 301.10 303.32 299.67 299.92 306.64 310.70 322.34 326.86 313.05 318.84 317.46 314.03 317.83 318.20 320.62 315.25 320.79 322.65 333.14 336.90 329.15 326.68 330.93 330.71 330.62 330.30 328.33 332.84 333.16 335.07 342.00 347.22 345.03 345.20 346.30 344.28 348.94 350.81 346.45 341.50 344.93 88,300 90,100 90,200 91,100 91,400 91,300 91,700 91,400 87,200 87,900 89,200 91,600 93,500 95,700 95,600 96,800 97,900 99,400 99,700 99,800 95,500 95,000 97,800 102,800 105,200 107,600 108,900 110,000 112,000 112,600 114,100 113,800 106,300 106,100 108,900 110,900 112,500 114,900 116,600 117,500 119,000 117,700 117,200 116,300 110,500 109,500 112,400 115,700 118,500 121,500 121,400 122,800 123,800 548.63 559.40 565.39 561.34 569.88 554.21 589.26 592.96 584.82 577.81 573.13 588.06 592.92 584.22 578.14 584.77 603.88 604.76 601.43 621.23 605.63 607.34 623.90 627.99 639.48 646.65 643.32 657.37 666.85 651.48 681.90 692.65 694.90 652.91 687.02 693.41 703.64 699.74 715.17 713.22 736.06 678.46 729.96 726.14 701.06 639.54 707.49 705.39 722.87 741.90 748.70 752.72 742.77 120 Oct. 382,800 350.34 123,000 714.99 Nov. 382,500 350.02 123,300 776.75 Dec. 377,800 351.87 123,200 763.75 1988 Jan. 362,100 339.84 112,800 736.99 Feb. 370,000 347.26 114,100 689.64 Mar. 375,000 350.62 117,800 752.84 Apr. 369,600 338.89 119,300 748.70 May 369,900 342.80 120,100 757.20 June 372,300 343.17 122,700 779.39 July 362,700 340.40 121,200 778.87 Aug. 370,400 345.38 121,300 776.14 Sep. 374,700 346.39 124,100 777.45 Oct. 372,900 356.38 123,000 786.37 Nov. 374,400 360.61 123,100 830.65 Dec. 367,100 362.33 121,800 823.25 1989 Jan. 353,300 359.41 113,100 797.16 Feb. 360,200 356.96 113,600 778.96 Mar. 363,700 360.98 116,700 821.38 Apr. 361,700 359.20 119,000 835.89 May 362,100 356.96 120,600 818.44 June 364,100 358.30 123,300 828.07 July 354,800 356.72 122,600 834.77 Aug. 362,600 360.51 124,100 828.37 Sop. 365,000 360.14 125,900 868.23 Oct. 360,000 361.72 124,100 857.38 Nov. 357,400 366.92 123,900 891.70 Dec. 349,200 372.25 123,300 862.07 1990 Jan. 332,900 366.83 112,600 823.37 Fob. 338,500 368.56 112,400 827.64 Mar. 342,900 376.29 115,100 596.54 Apr. 337,700 364.97 113,400 779.80 May 341,500 377.03 114,500 822.11 Juno 343,900 378.42 115,500 819.36 July 333,700 378.38 113,800 815.78 Aug. 339,700 377.68 113,700 606.70 Sop. 341,600 376.66 113,500 853.76 Oct. 338,200 378.96 112,300 619.28 Nov. 333,100 379.25 110,800 635.38 Doc. 326,400 338.13 106,800 609.61 1991 Jan. 316,100 379.34 100,300 835.67 Fob. 320,600 381.55 96,500 847.39 Mar. 323,200 383.63 98,500 844.88 Apr. 321,600 382.21 99,700 841.66 May 322,700 382.21 100,800 844.73 Juno 324,100 386.05 102,300 843.01 July 316,800 381.30 100,700 845.15 l.Number of employees in the manufacturing industry. 2.Average weekly earning in the manufacturing industry. 3.Number of employees in the construction industry. 121 4.Average weekly earning in the construction industry. 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 MONTHS Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. “BY June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. reams 59,000 59,400 59,600 59,000 59,000 59,300 59,900 59,200 59,000 58,500 58,300 59,000 59,400 60,100 60,200 59,800 59,900 60,200 60,600 60,500 60,000 59,600 59,300 59,400 59,300 59,700 59,700 59,300 59,300 59,700 59,700 59,500 58,600 58,500 58,400 57,700 57,600 57,700 57,400 57,000 56,700 56,600 56,600 34,600 56,300 55,400 56,100 56,400 55,300 56,300 55,200 54,300 122 TEWER‘ 402.79 421.26 401.60 389.65 390.85 393.22 391.02 392.00 408.00 455.20 463.61 452.09 449.63 465.19 435.51 417.76 427.60 423.87 428.79 464.09 487.81 491.78 501.90 497.90 473.98 495.81 472.42 469.64 466.88 476.39 465.68 499.28 503.79 521.11 525.71 513.20 512.00 518.46 506.09 517.69 499.50 505.60 519.79 304.80 530.32 560.05 620.49 581.30 529.99 543.35 514.56 524.40 ELEM7 24,800 24,900 24,900 24,800 24,800 24,900 25,200 25,300 25,100 24,800 24,900 24,900 24,800 24,800 24,800 24,700 24,700 25,000 25,600 25,500 25,400 24,800 24,800 24,800 24,700 24,600 24,600 24,600 24,400 24,600 25,000 25,000 24,700 24,700 24,700 24,800 24,500 24,500 24,500 24,500 24,400 24,700 9,600 9,700 24,400 24,300 24,300 24,200 24,200 24,000 23,900 23,800 aLwaR° 413.34 419.24 410.35 403.92 410.18 413.88 414.54 448.16 467.42 463.76 480.24 465.70 470.81 483.57 472.94 470.55 456.46 455.52 449.96 481.50 490.35 503.70 515.57 496.34 503.18 524.61 497.80 503.14 488.92 501.83 490.99 520.57 551.69 550.95 578.16 558.39 541.68 542.88 537.35 527.85 538.32 525.68 519.84 540.35 540.60 573.70 575.46 567.60 590.67 590.39 581.09 580.13 1985 1986 1987 1988 Apr. June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. 54,100 54,000 53,400 53,000 53,000 52,500 52,100 52,200 51,400 51,300 50,900 50,600 50,200 49,900 49,400 49,100 48,500 47,500 47,700 47,600 44,900 45,200 45,300 43,300 43,100 40,000 42,800 26,600 42,300 41,600 41,500 41,000 40,500 40,400 40,400 39,700 39,800 40,000 39,800 39,800 39,900 39,900 40,000 40,200 40,600 40,500 40,500 40,600 40,300 40,500 40,300 40,400 40,200 123 518.90 529.20 557.69 559.47 565.65 575.74 589.36 574.73 561.56 599.63 553.42 545.27 552.42 554.21 551.60 583.78 584.99 592.59 624.70 596.96 588.63 ‘605.05 587.73 591.34 600.07 615.68 590.24 477.59 595.50 641.45 685.97 671.23 678.26 640.90 654.91 638.15 631.31 633.23 686.99 688.42 716.72 743.15 745.07 698.21 694.59 736.79 706.48 687.52 687.52 673.32 664.26 669.06 664.47 23,900 24,000 24,200 24,200 23,700 23,700 23,700 23,700 23,700 23,600 23,500 23,400 23,400 23,700 23,800 23,800 23,400 23,300 23,400 23,300 23,200 23,200 23,100 23,100 23,100 23,100 23,500 23,500 20,800 20,600 22,800 22,900 22,800 22,800 22,700 22,700 22,800 22,800 23,200 23,200 22,700 22,600 22,600 22,600 22,600 22,500 22,400 22,600 22,600 22,900 23,300 23,300 22,800 576.15 585.90 599.71 616.28 641.78 629.58 652.74 633.14 625.10 632.91 621.65 619.06 627.27 610.61 623.17 604.78 667.93 703.95 696.78 663.34 650.60 669.11 654.99 649.30 647.79 644.54 642.64 576.67 744.11 737.38 677.30 681.33 676.82 700.13 690.99 682.08 678.51 677.04 686.45 686.71 699.08 733.04 687.04 727.72 679.90 670.23 7718.96 657.61 707.19 696.14 721.11 712.75 736.50 124 Oct. 40,800 654.46 22,800 740.15 Nov. 40,900 652.76 22,900 736.56 Dec. 41,200 699.34 22,900 743.04 1989 Jan. 40,300 642.80 22,900 745.04 Feb. 40,400 647.54 23,000 732.34 Mar. 40,600 622.05 23,000 739.47 Apr. 38,800 634.81 23,000 749.83 May 38,700 624.87 23,000 745.27 June 38,900 608.79 23,200 734.60 July 38,500 609.52 23,600 729.17 Aug. 21,300 637.78 23,500 704.16 Sep. 18,800 626.94 22,700 769.52 Oct. 19,700 652.69 22,500 784.80 Nov. 19,300 629.53 22,400 790.27 Dec. 37,800 628.62 22,400 817.78 1990 Jan. 36,600 633.29 22,300 795.22 Feb. 36,900 633.36 22,300 779.68 Mar. 35,000 634.92 22,300 779.64 Apr. 36,700 633.04 22,400 767.37 May 36,900 643.36 22,400 766.04 June 35,900 641.03 22,500 753.86 July 35,700 647.60 22,900 769.63 Aug. 35,600 659.15 22,900 752.80 Sop. 35,600 669.61 22,300 792.51 Oct. 35,900 701.78 22,200 796.72 Nov. 35,600 696.80 22,200 802.68 Dec. 35,600 664.97 22,100 786.92 1991 Jan. 34,900 675.68 22,200 789.70 Feb. 35,100 694.55 22,100 804.69 Mar. 35,200 668.68 22,100 803.73 Apr. 35,200 656.00 22,100 796.21 May 35,000 652.38 22,100 801.10 June 35,000 648.76 22,200 789.26 July 35,300 635.90 22,600 795.07 5 .Number of employees in the telephone and telegam industry. 6.Average weekly earning in the telephone and telegam industry. 7 .Number of employees in the electric, gas and sanitary services. 8.Average weekly earning in the electric, gas and sanitary services. 1980 1981 1982 1983 [1984 MONTHS Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. WHEM9 245,000 245,600 247,300 245,100 245,900 246,400 244,900 245,100 245,800 246,300 246,900 247,800 246,300 246,700 247,500 247,300 247,300 248,400 246,300 247,100 247,700 248,600 248,800 248,500 246,400 246,200 246,600 246,600 246,600 246,800 243,900 243,900 243,200 242,200 242,000 421,700 237,400 236,300 237,500 238,400 237,900 239,400 239,300 240,600 241,100 242,200 242,600 242,200 240,600 241,400 243,100 243,700 125 wawaa“’ 301.18 299.83 301.13 302.44 300.58 301.38 304.37 301.32 305.04 306.16 313.96 314.42 321.58 323.95 328.10 327.75 330.75 327.62 332.63 337.19 334.43 344.96 348.23 348.30 357.93 363.65 357.96 353.81 358.52 360.02 361.95 364.62 364.34 366.49 374.40 380.16 387.54 378.62 383.53 378.13 376.50 377.88 380.46 359.07 381.58 389.06 395.64 399.19 395.37 395.20 391.23 402.34 TWERn' 249,000,000 254,000,000 256,000,000 248,000,000 254,000,000 258,000,000 254,000,000 257,000,000 261,000,000 266,000,000 272,000,000 272,000,000 268,000,000 273,000,000 279,000,000 277,000,000 280,000,000 283,000,000 278,000,000 287,000,000 291,000,000 292,000,000 296,000,000 294,000,000 286,000,000 340,000,000 295,000,000 288,000,000 293,000,000 298,000,000 289,000,000 295,000,000 298,000,000 299,000,000 307,000,000 374,000,000 297,000,000 294,000,000 301,000,000 303,000,000 305,000,000 310,000,000 298,000,000 278,000,000 316,000,000 322,000,000 332,000,000 329,000,000 316,000,000 320,000,000 319,000,000 325,000,000 S'I'Isznn12 892,800 904,100 912,800 895,200 907,100 911,600 890,000 901,400 906,900 908,200 905,300 895,600 875,900 891,000 900,000 901,100 905,400 913,700 895,800 907,900 914,800 906,700 901,700 887,300 863,100 1,052,400 879,300 869,600 873,600 878,800 852,700 863,500 867,400 859,100 853,900 1,022,600 818,600 825,700 835,300 837,000 840,200 849,800 817,100 811,600 855,100 855,000 856,500 847,000 828,000 841,200 849,200 845,100 1985 1986 1987 1988 244,800 246,700 246,600 248,200 247,900 248,600 249,000 248,600 245,700 245,800 247,000 246,100 245,600 245,700 242,400 242,500 241,100 242,000 243,000 242,200 237,500 237,600 238,300 238,500 238,200 238,600 237,900 237,700 238,400 238,600 239,300 240,100 235,400 235,200 236,000 236,100 236,200 237,200 234,000 234,100 234,000 234,300 234,000 233,200 230,800 231,800 232,700 230,200 230,700 231,800 231,200 231,800 232,900 126 400.60 403.10 404.46 403.77 406.73 410.08 411.92 420.92 417.58 414.63 414.32 405.75 407.96 419.14 420.66 414.32 421.47 415.45 426.72 436.24 435.86 436.54 436.97 430.14 433.96 437.76 431.67 429.79 435.85 440.63 450.07 453.66 457.25 456.32 446.31 450.30 460.31 458.89 462.22 458.89 477.88 470.78 479.42 473.69 477.92 484.38 480.95 493.01 487.30 485.01 494.92 480.53 490.81 326,000,000 330,000,000 325,000,000 331,000,000 339,000,000 341,000,000 346,000,000 349,000,000 331,000,000 337,000,000 338,000,000 334,000,000 340,000,000 346,000,000 342,000,000 344,000,000 352,000,000 350,000,000 364,000,000 363,000,000 347,000,000 345,000,000 353,000,000 350,000,000 353,000,000 354,000,000 352,000,000 342,000,000 364,000,000 359,000,000 371,000,000 370,000,000 356,000,000 350,000,000 360,000,000 359,000,000 368,000,000 374,000,000 372,000,000 373,000,000 381,000,000 379,000,000 387,000,000 382,000,000 360,000,000 364,000,000 377,000,000 371,000,000 374,000,000 379,000,000 376,000,000 377,000,000 384,000,000 849,400 856,700 840,100 854,400 858,200 853,400 851,800 843,400 820,100 827,600 835,300 830,500 834,500 838,600 823,200 832,600 835,100 832,600 836,500 826,500 800,500 807,700 814,600 808,300 808,900 809,400 804,300 796,000 815,600 811,600 811,700 804,300 779,200 786,300 795,600 791,900 797,100 804,100 791,600 800,700 805,300 802,600 802,400 797,000 768,900 778,900 788,400 782,300 783,600 790,200 778,700 787,200 794,700 127 Oct. 233,000 496.44 389,000,000 792,500 Nov. 234,400 496.37 397,000,000 795,700 Dec. 234,900 492.53 395,000,000 787,900 1989 Jan. 229,500 490.68 373,000,000 759,100 Feb. 229,700 499.53 375,000,000 766,900 Mar. 230,500 501.42 385,000,000 774,500 Apr. 229,000 509.76 388,000,000 771,500 May 228,900 497.07 383,000,000 773,300 June 230,000 505.02 389,000,000 779,500 July 227,300 497.79 383,000,000 766,800 Aug. 226,800 493.49 376,000,000 758,300 Sep. 226,400 496.87 383,000,000 . 758,800 Oct. 226,400 496.49 380,000,000 752,700 Nov. 227,000 503.26 386,000,000 750,000 Dec. 226,300 501.40 392,000,000 759,000 1990 Jan. 220,400 500.83 366,000,000 724,800 Feb. 220,800 512.86 372,000,000 730,900 Mar. 222,000 520.51 353,000,000 737,300 Apr. 220,100 521.14 367,000,000 730,300 May 221,300 520.13 379,000,000 736,600 Juno 222,000 524.37 381,000,000 739,800 July 219,800 521.88 375,000,000 725,900 Aug. 218,900 519.99 352,000,000 730,800 Sop. 217,400 522.96 381,000,000 730,400 Oct. 217,200 517.78 353,000,000 725,800 Nov. 215,600 518.16 351,000,000 717,300 Dec. 214,500 528.99 330,000,000 705,400 1991 Jan. 211,000 527.39 356,000,000 684,500 Fob. 210,000 530.46 358,000,000 684,300 Mar. 210,700 529.92 360,000,000 689,700 Apr. 210,100 533.27 360,000,000 688,700 May 210,400 531.84 361,000,000 691,000 June 211,400 531.88 364,000,000 695,000 July 209,300 522.15 356,000,000 684,700 9.Number of employees in the wholesale trade. 10.Average weekly earning in the wholesale trade. 11. Total employees: (MAEM‘MAWER) + (COEM‘COWER) + (TEEM‘T'WER) + (ELEM‘ELWER) + (WI-IE M *WHWER) 12.Total employees: MAEM+COEM+TEEM+ELEM 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 MONTHS Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sep. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. avawaan3 278.7923 281.2262 280.3370 277.3917 279.5040 283.0258 285.8515 285.0475 287.7404 292.9137 300.4976 304.0288 306.0494 306.0392 309.6578 307.9000 308.7859 309.3989 310.7902 316.0943 317.5910 322.5741 327.7829 331.5367 331.7984 323.1738 335.2793 330.8679 334.9909 338.6093 338.5131 341.5257 344.0817 348.5571 359.1656 365.9563 362.9184 356.0961 360.3248 362.5734 362.6355 365.1448 365.1910 342.4308 369.4343 376.1450 387.1650 388.2035 381.0661 380.8389 376.0143 384.2115 128 DAVEWERL‘ 356.5119 356.4338 350.4213 344.1584 344.6412 344.7331 346.0672 342.1939 344.1870 348.2921 355.1981 355.5893 354.6343 350.1593 352.6854 348.6977 347.7318 345.6971 342.2800 345.0812 341.4957 347.9763 353.9772 357.6448 357.1565 347.1255 362.4641 356.5387 357.5143 353.8237 352.9855 354.6477 354.3581 354.2247 366.1219 375.3398 371.0822 363.3634 367.3036 365.8662 364.8245 366.2436 365.1910 342.0887 365.7766 371.3179 380.6932 381.3394 370.6868 368.3162 362.5982 369.0793 WEEK15 4.428 4.143 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.000 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.000 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.000 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.143 4.428 4.285 INC16 1578.634 1476.705 1551.665 1474.719 1526.071 1477.181 1532.385 1515.234 1474.841 1542.238 1522.024 1574.549 1570.320 1400.637 1561.691 1494.169 1539.756 1481.312 1515.616 1528.019 1463.309 1540.839 1516.792 1583.651 1581.489 1388.502 1604.991 1527.768 1583.073 1516.135 1563.020 1570.380 1518.425 1568.507 1568.832 1662.004 1643.152 1453.454 1626.420 1567.737 1615.443 1569.354 1617.066 1514.769 1567.353 1644.196 1631.270 1688.571 1641.401 1525.934 1605.585 1581.505 1985 1986 1987 1988 383.5105 385.5860 387.1622 387.4213 394.7109 399.0612 406.7177 413.3659 403.0310 406.7681 404.9173 402.7547 407.6932 412.2248 415.3756 413.4164 421.3402 420.1642 434.6941 439.1739 433.2489 427.2649 433.0247 432.8778 436.3441 437.4939 438.0977 429.9757 446.0476 441.8179 456.8819 459.8150 456.4501 444.9130 452.4996 453.0645 461.0575 465.0854 469.4475 466.1348 473.1263 471.6871 482.5151 479.3093 468.2775 467.8053 477.9316 474.0379 477.0943 479.6630 482.6752 479.0377 483.3112 129 368.4058 369.6894 369.4296 367.2240 371.6675 376.1180 381.8945 388.1370 377.7235 379.0942 376.6673 373.2666 377.1445 380.6323 383.1878 378.5864 384.4345 382.6632 392.6776 395.6522 387.5213 383.1972 388.3630 389.2786 393.4573 391.6687 389.4202 381.5224 394.7324 389.6102 403.2497 404.0554 397.9513 385.8742 390.7596 388.5630 393.0584 394.8093 398.1743 392.0394 394.9302 392.4186 400.4275 397.4372 416.9880 417.3107 393.3593 386.6541 388.8299 389.6532 390.5139 385.6986 383.5803 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.000 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.000 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.000 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.143 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.285 4.428 4.428 4.285 1631.301 1584.119 1635.834 1626.068 1592.595 1665.451 1636.418 1718.671 1672.560 1516.377 1667.883 1599.447 1669.996 1631.009 1696.756 1676.381 1647.302 1694.433 1682.624 1751.948 1715.945 1532.789 1719.671 1668.059 1742.229 1678.300 1724.353 1689.381 1691.428 1725.194 1727.925 1789.157 1762.128 1543.497 1730.284 1664.993 1740.462 1691.758 1763.116 1735.950 1692.276 1737.629 1715.832 1759.852 1846.423 1728.918 1741.795 1656.813 1721.739 1669.664 1729.196 1707.874 1643.642 130 Oct. 490.6820 388.8130 4.428 1721.664 Nov. 499.1575 396.4714 4.285 1698.880 Dec. 501.0876 397.6886 4.428 1760.965 1989 Jan. 490.9968 386.6116 4.428 1711.916 Feb. 488.7382 383.0237 4.000 1532.095 Mar. 497.0740 385.6276 4.428 1707.559 Apr. 502.9233 388.3577 4.285 1664.113 May 495.3603 380.4610 4.428 1684.681 June 499.5989 382.8344 4.285 1640.445 July 499.1258 382.1790 4.428 1692.289 Aug. 495.2890 378.3720 4.428 1675.431 Sep. 504.0949 381.3123 4.285 1633.923 Oct. 504.2399 379.6987 4.428 1681.306 Nov. 514.2811 386.0969 4.285 1654.425 Dec. 516.2449 387.2805 4.428 1714.878 1990 Jan. 505.1379 373.8992 4.428 1655.626 Feb. 508.6628 375.9518 4.000 1503.807 Mar. 478.5745 350.3474 4.428 1551.338 Apr. 502.2652 365.8159 4.285 1567.521 May 514.3788 374.9116 4.428 1660.109 June 515.2199 375.7986 4.285 1610.297 July 515.9860 372.8223 4.428 1650.857 Aug. 481.4044 343.8603 4.428 1522.613 Sep. 521.3190 370.2550 4.285 1586.543 Oct. 486.4320 343.5254 4.428 1521.130 Nov. 489.4314 345.8879 4.285 1482.130 Doc. 467.8256 330.3853 4.428 1462.946 1991 Jan. 520.2614 363.8192 4.428 1610.991 Fob. 522.6611 363.9702 4.000 1455.881 Mar. 522.2039 364.1589 4.428 1612.496 Apr. 522.0847 363.3157 4.285 1556.808 May 522.3223 362.7238 4.428 1606.141 June 523.7789 362.2261 4.285 1552.139 July 519.3578 357.6844 4.428 1583.827 13.Average weekly earning: TWER/ST'EM 14.Deflated average weekly earning: AVEWER/CPINY 15.Number of weeks in the month: number of days in the month /7 16.Deflated monthly income: DAVEWER‘WEEK APPENDIX D DERIVATION OF THE REDUCED—FORM EQUATIONS FOR q: and pf APPENDIX D DERIVATION OF THE REDUCED-FORM EQUATIONS FOR q,' AND p; Using equations (3.1),(3.2),(3.3) and (3.4) in Chapter III, we can derive the reduced-form equations for q,' and p; For doing this, we first need to solve for the reduced- form equations for q,' and p; as functions of all the exogenous variables in the system. ‘ The reduced-form equation for q," is obtained by substituting p; in equation (3.4) into p; in equation (3.3). Note that p; = p;, since the transportation costs to region 0 is assumed to be equal to zero in equation (3.2). q.” - 31(939.'+Plh.'+l3§f.‘)+flip;+l3§m’ (D.l) +316” +P§P$+B;P;+B§m{+flif{ +1. . 31$; . 9153 B; . B; B‘.’ 9: " hrl ¢+ T "'1’... 1 14:9; 1410'.“ 14391-010; 14:9; (D2) Bi r 95 r B; . 65 p + p + ”3,4 '+(‘ 1410;" 1410;" 14:0: 14:01,! 4. The reduced-form equation for p; is obtained by substituting q," in equation (3.3) into q,' in equation (3.4). 131 132 p; - 9;<9'.p,'.+9’.v,2+9;m.'+01f.’ +921»; (D3) +620;+BZM.°+Bif.°)+BZh,'+B;f,’+v, " a; 3 p7 9:9; 0 P = 15+ ‘74 " I-B‘IB; 1410;" 14:9; " (0.4) + 3:63 "1’4 B233 ,1, 629? . 1-0‘.’9:' 1419:" 1419;" , 133953;, 0:13;,“ 1:0: 192‘ 714:9. 14:01' 14:15. The reduced-form equation for p", is obtained by substituting the reduced-form equation for p; into p; = up; in equation (3.1). . ca: 4:». on; f, can; . P = 1 " l-ata; 14:0. 14:13:" + can; ., 4:01., can: . (D5) "'1 ‘ t T 143:9; 14:9. 14:11:10" c9335 . will; . 6153131 + + m‘ + ‘ +t, 14:9. " 14:9; 1470.], Let K 1 €035; The ' ' = — . n we can sunphfy (D.5) as, 1-929’.‘ 133 '3‘ u)/th, +[( ”jg/K16“ 15 IBIS p; = [(1- 69333 . 05553 +[( . _)/KIp,.+I(_,)/K1m°. 1" 135 1 5 (D.6) 9:9: )IKIr.‘+ +[( :B’B’p/np; 1 5 155 +11 ”DD/Kim {+I( ”BU/K1494, 1"915 n 5 The reduced-form equation for q,’ is obtained by substituting the reduced-form equation for p; into the p", in the demand equation for NYC region (equation (3.1)). 9199; . BIC B7 q.’ =11 . ,I/KIh. +I< )IKV.‘ 1’9195 1-5135 .[(pch:p:)lKlp;+ [(B‘f ”Bu/K94" m. 1' 135 n 5 (D.7) 11':l ’i’wxw «(:1 ”’B’IIKF 9+9»; 155 1 5 «up: ”pg/KP +9;)m. '+(I(”’ ”gnu/KP +921r.'+ : 1 5 1 5 Equations (D.6) and (D.7) are the reduced-form equations for price and quantity in the NYC region. The coefficients on the information variables in the reduced-form equation for price are as follows: 134 Coefficient for the f,” variable: (D.8) a2 = .—1_fl = CB7 r _ 413:9; 1-9;<9‘.’+c9.) 1-9Y92 Coefficient for the f," variable: 1—919: g c929: _ 49:9: 1-9;(9‘.’+c9:> 1-919'; (0.9) a, = Coefficient for the f,’ variable: ebgfli (D.10) as = 1‘9195 a c0584 1- 013551 1'15;(Bi+cfii) 1-979: We can express equation (3.11) in Chapter III as, ,, _ +9: + 4:9: ' 1-919‘.’ + c911 1-9;<9:+c91’) (0.11) c6293 l-PKBMBD By collecting terms (D.11) can be expressed as, _ «99939992» 1-9’;(9‘.’+c9:) (D.12) 8' 135 The coefficients on the information variables in the reduced-form equation for quantity are as follows: Coefficient for the f,’I variable: CBIB; (D.13) Y2 = l-plfsr = 291097 ' l- C9591 l‘ps(91+cfln) 1-919; Coefficient for the f," variable: ebiflifli 1-919: . c919:9: (1114) Y5 = n r u o r 1_ c9591 1795(91+091) 1-919; Coefficient for the f,’ variable: 6316291 (0.15) v. = ___1-0,.9,' = 43,939, , +91 1- 99591 1’95(91+Cpn) 1—919: We can express equation (3.7) in Chapter III as, 9,3: c919; ,_ c919:92 1439980 143911491) (D.16) 1 0315;“ r T l 0 ' +p‘ l‘psmn‘wpr) By collecting terms (D.16) can be expressed as, 136 .. c9k93+92<92+92>> , v = +9 (D.17) n a r ‘ 1755(BH’CBI) Substitute (D.12) into (D.17), am) 7, =19: + a') + 9: APPENDIX B THE ASYMPTOTIC COVARIANCE MATRIX FOR THE TWO-STAGE LEAST SQUARES ESTIMATOR WITH SEASONAL ARIMA ERRORS APPENDIX B THE ASYMPTOTIC COVARIANCE MATRIX FOR THE TWO-STAGE LEAST SQUARES ESTIMATOR WITH SEASONAL ARIMA ERRORS Demand equation for apples in the NYC region is, (El) 4" a: fxpfiyet where q,’ is the per capita quantity of apples at time t, f,(0,a) is the demand equation, 0 and a are vectors of regession parameters and et is the random error term at time t. Here, a is the parameter vector of the price equation that we use to obtain the fitted values for the price variable. These fitted values are then used in the demand equation in place of the observed values of the price variable. 0 denotes the vector of the parameters for all other variables in the demand equation. The equation to estimate the fitted values for the price variable is, (El) P}. = s,(¢)+V, where p,’, is the retail price of apples at time t, g,(a) is the price equation, a is the vector of regession parameters and v, is the random error term at time t. The fitted values of the price is estimated by equation (E2) and is replaced in the demand equation in place of the price variable. Nonlinear least squares method is used irn estimating the equations in the presence of a seasonal error structure. The demand equation and the price equation are 137 138 both defined to be nonlinear to obtain the general form of the asymptotic covariance matrix. The criterion function to obtain the estimate [3, B, in the demand equation by nonlinear least squares is, (93) 09) = 21,10,509»)? The first order conditions for a minimum are, E.4 - r _‘ ( ) 2 “(69 .e,)|, =0 Equation (E.4) defines the standard problem in the nonlinear optimization, which can be solved by number of methods. One most frequently used method is the Gauss- Newton method. This method provides the correct estimate of the asymptotic covariance matrix for the parameter estimates.1 Divide both sides of (E4) by -2, (1:3) 3" =0 Err-1 ('35-‘90 The above equation can be rewritten in matrix form as: I (E.6) (6193):, . 0 where 828 is a (T‘xK) matrix and e is a (Txl) vector. T denotes the number of observations and K denotes the number of estimated parameters in the demand equation. lWilliam H. Greene, p.336. 139 Following the central limit theorem that provides the asymptotic normality result of the least squares estimator,1 we can write the following equality: 'm1, = (E.7) T 33 .e 0 Using the mean-value theorem,2 we can write (E.7) as, T431]: = T -1rz( afl-fllg 60 60 (E.8) . .1. if . 1 1’9: - I T(a9= .01, 1133 .apnnfiu 9) where, %I‘ = -3—B—|a. The mean value of B, 8, is a value between 8 and the estimate of 0, 6. Note that in equation (E.8), T-m‘810,°el’ = o.ThiS result comes from (E6). We can then write equation (E.8) as, I 'mi’ a -1 fl T an .8 I 1‘63: .9)“ (5.9) . .1. 1’1 - 1136.65107719 9) Define, .. -1 if . .1. 1’1 A 1(apz '7" 7(89 ‘89)“ and a 'mi’ K T 33 .e Then we can write (E.9) as, 1William H. Greene, p.315-l6. 2See, Alpha C. Chiang, ' 3rd ed., (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 1984), p. 261. 140 (5.10) (718-0) = A".K Note that the price variable in the demand equation (equation (E.l)) is the fitted values of the price variable from equation (E.2). Following the mean-value theorem we can write K in equation (E.10) as, K = T'Vz( afie)“ + 59 (E.ll) [%(gg‘m + %g—I-gmlfila-fi) where, %I‘ = "%li’ The mean value of a, a, is a value between a and the estimate of a, a . Define, I B a —l(_yL _¢)|‘ + lbliin. 7' 8988 T 89 81! We can write (E.ll) as, (E.12) K = T'W(%I.e)|, + Nina-a) Substitute (E. 12) into (E.10), (5.13) «719-9) + A"[T"”(%’.¢)I, + Nina -a>1 The criterion function to estimate a by nonlinear least squares is, 02.14) so) - 23., 0,2114)? The first order conditions for the minimum are, 141 (5.15) ~22); (%ygl, = 0 Divide both sides of the equation (E.15) by +2, (E.l6) 2; (Sign, = 0 The above equation can be written in matrix form as, I (E.l7) (2i 3,)“ = 0 8a where, 613- is a (T‘xZ) matrix and v is a (Txl) vector. T denotes the number of a observations and Z denotes the number of estimated parameters. Following the central limit theorem, (E.18) T'mi’y = 0 311 Following the mean-value theorem, we can write (E.18) T “2 .v T "'( .v)|. 4713:5281. + 43 71.177144) where g—Vh = ‘33? .The mean value of a, a, is a value between a and the estimate of a, a .Note that In 6equation (E.19) T'mgiyh :- 0. This result comes from (E.l7). We a can write equation (E.19) as, I'd/3%, v s [—_(.?I v”. (E20) 1 (29125 _ a- +T( ad .03 ”111/71 a) Define, 142 . -12’3’ 195’ as C T8012 .14, + T601 87." Then we can write (E.20) as, I (13.21) fine-a) = c". (T‘mg- .v) Substitute (E.21) into (E.13), (719-9) = A“ [rm-9’5 01. (13.22) + a. clam-3'») 8a In order to find the expected value of (E22), we need to have the expected values for A, B and C. The expected value for A is: ' g _ 9! _a_r_ 9(4) El T 69 331,] The expected value for B is: -11 900+ agent—1.13 The expected value for C is: 910+ +04% %"J Note that the expected values of the first terms in A, B and C equal to zero since the expected values of the error terms are defined to be equal to zero (i.e., E(e) = 0 and E( v ) = 0). 143 Define, r=(-§-fétet)’|.+8.'lC .(::-—'* v,)’ where, * denotes element-by-element multiplication. (E22) can be written as, (E23) fitB—p) = A" 1"” 2:11} (E24) anti-m - m“ T" 23mm] Ema-BY] = (E25) l’af. 3f. -1 -1 1 95’ if,“ (%(53 a—BM) T 21,,E(r{,')(1.(—— as an up tub-m -- “‘3’" «3" at. a: at. -1 [(6—5 a—Bna 2,21% 1.6K an '63 )1.) The above equation is the asymptotic covariance matrix. Since in practice, we cannot evaluate the matrices defined in (E26) at B and a , we evaluate them at B and a. We can write (E26) as: FEB-5):] = (E27) “’3‘ a. t 3 [(8B 6B ear. —)I,)'1 ,,t£(r;.’)«-aT3 a—fl )w where, 144 38. r =(%*e,-"--5-)’l3+80( WM, and, E(B)= [fl-(a); Z: I E(C) = EI%,-:§a! %IJ To estimate (E27), we need to define matrices %Ipaa 312' and %h. We also a need to define eh and VJ. in ’3' ch is the estimated residual: from the demand equation with instrument for the price variable. v). is the estimated residuals from the equation to estimate the fitted values for the price variable. In defining %|’,a%|.and 81;", we should first write out the demand equation with the instrument for the price variable and the equation to estimate the fitted values for the price variable. Demand equation with instrument for the price variable: (E28) mm = Auq: -= Bo+B,A.,p.'.+Aur.'+a+¢L‘x1+u“)e, We can rewrite (E28) as, (E29) 1; = A124: ‘ BO+BlAIIpI'+A11fI' *¢%-1+Q‘:-n*¢¢et-u+‘ The equation to estimate the fitted values for the price variable in (E28) is, (E30) p,’ -= g,(a) = ao+a,p;+a2h,'+a,m,'+aj;'+v, Substitute the estimate of (E30) into (E29), 145 f: = A124: ‘ Bo+B,A12(&0+&,p;+&2h,'+&3m,'+&fl) (E31) +Anfi’ +¢‘:-1+¢‘c-12+¢¢‘r-13+‘: Define, 1 A139; A125, é:-1*°es-u 5:42" :43 3f, 3‘" ' B . _ 1 A094,; A121; ér-1*¢ér-13 ér-u*“r-t3 . 1 P; mt, hi. I: 38:. . 6a ‘ ‘. L l pyT m; h; f; 0 61AM): 61AM: 61AM: “Ali: 93' ___ . . 6a ‘ . . . . _0 61AM; 91AM; 91AM; btAufi'. 93., an .nd 21;: 6B 6a 6a vectors e,..e,, 9,...9Tin (E.27).(E.27) is calculated by using GAUSS program version 2.1 To estimate (E27), we substitute matrices, |& and the for personal computers. This calculation is applied to the demand equation with instrument for the price variable that is reported in Table 42 in Chapter IV. APPENDIX F EXPECTED VALUE OF THE CHANGE IN APPLE SALES ASSOCIATED WITH HEALTH RISK INFORMATION APPENDIX F EXPECTED VALUE OF THE CHANGE IN APPLE SALES ASSOCIATED WITH HEALTH RISK INFORMATION Let q(pJf) be the individual demand function for apples when health risk is not present in the market and let q(pfi') be the demand function for apples when health risk is present in the market. Here, pt is the apple price, If is the absence of the reported risk, and f,1 is the presence of the reported risk at time t. These demand functions are demonstrated in Figure 1. : q(p.°f) % q(p.i) fl Figure F.l. Change in Apple Sales Asociated With Health-Risk Information Here, 4,0 denotes per capita quantity of apples demanded when risk is not present, 4,1 denotes per capita quantity of apples demanded when risk is present. p,' is the retail price of apples at time t. 146 147 The change in per capita apple purchases at time t is, (El) A4, = a} - q? The expected value of the change in per capita apple purchases at time t is obtained by taking the expectation of (RI): (F2) E(Aq.) = E(q?) - 15(4)) The expected value of the change in per capita apple sales at time t is obtained by multplying (F2) by price of apples at time t, 1):. This gives an estimate of the value of the shaded area in Figure RI. The total value of the change in apple sales is obtained by multipliying the change in per capita apple sales with the population at time t. In this study, the demand function for apples is specified as log-linear. The following equation is the individual demand function for apples that is specified in this study when health risk is present in the market. Note that the variables are seasonally differenced since the dependent variable in the demand equation is nonstationary. 139:1 —lnq,‘_n-B0+B1(lnp,-lnp 42) (F3) + 320}. 15:12) +¢£bl + Qet-tz"'¢°ec-13 +6: where B0, B1, B2, 4) and 4’ are the regression coefficients and e, is the random error term. Here, 4) and ¢ are the seasonal ARIMA coefficients. (R3) can be written as, mq:-1nq,‘.,,+p,+p,anp,-mp m) (F.4) + 520}! 751-12) +¢et-l +¢ebn+¢°et~13 +6, where, 148 104:1”N (p902) e,~N (0,02) (F.4) can be written as, (F5) 4:54.142 p," ”:2; camel-13...) ec ea. where, c = 436'_1+¢£‘_u+¢0£'_13 and q} ~Iognoma1(e“°”*.e’"‘°’(e°’ -1» e"~lognormal(e '3”; “(ea-1)) The expected value of individual demand for apples when risk is present in the market is, (F.6) 5(4)) 8:5,}.01/2 where, liq“ is the estimate of big" and o is the estimate of a which are obtained by estimating equation (FA). (F.6) can be written as, (F07) E(q‘l) =e &;n.‘0"|(~g.h'p|1)’m ’ ”19“.?” 149 where, 60, B1, Bl are the estimates of the regression parameters from equation (R4) and e is the estimate of c. The expected value of individual demand for apples when risk is not present in the market is identical to (R7) with the exclusion of 520: 711,): (F3) E(q?) =e H:u*ao*filwc’hP:-iz)‘e*°2/2 The expected value of the change in per capita purchases is obtained by subtracting (F.7) from (F8), ((3.8): E(Aq.) = e‘°"1"""“"-n’*‘*°’ ’2 (F3) 1“[e file—u -¢ fivn‘bz‘fi‘fc-uh APPENDIX G EXPECTED VALUE OF THE CHANGE IN THE CONSUMER SURPLUS ASSOCIATED WITH HEALTH-RISK INFORMATION APPENDIX G EXPECTED VALUE OF THE CHANGE IN THE CONSUMER SURPLUS ASSOCIATED WITH HEALTH-RISK INFORMATION Let q(pgf) be the individual demand function for apples when health risk is not present in the market and let q(pntf) be the individual demand function for apples when health-risk is present in the market. Here, pt is the apple price, f,0 is the absence of the reported risk and ff is the presence of the reported risk at time t. These demand functions are demonstrated in Figure G. 1. PA 1! Mn” (N) b q Figure G.l. Change in Consumer Surplus Associated with Health-Risk Information The consumer surplus is the area under the demand curve above the price that the consumer pays for the good. The consumer surplus for the demand curve when health-risk is present in the market is, 150 151 (6.1) CS,‘=L'I q(M'fip. The consumer surplus for the demand curve when health-risk is not present in the market is, (62) CS.°=L'I qwbdp. The change in consumer surplus is the difference between (6.1) and (G2). (G3) ACS,=cs,°-cs,‘ The expected value of the change in consumer surplus is obtained by taking the ewectation of (G3) Demand function for apples when health risk is present in the market is identical to the demand equation presented in Appendix F (Equation ES). The consumer surplus when health risk is present in the market is, 1 " 1 CS: ' 1;. 92¢; (GA) In B -’ 4 .. = L. (qtl-lz Pr ' Pt-t; 9" W4”) 6:“? d”; -3 ”vhf PM“ (GS) cs: = mime” ""”“"’3’:i" 1 where, c = $6,_1+0€‘_u+¢06,_13 and (6.5) is infinity for Blz-l. Therefore, the consumer surplus should be calculated conditional that the own price elasticity of apples is greater than unity. 152 (1,1 ~ lognormal(e'”°z’2,e2“‘°z(e°1—l)) ee‘ ~ lognormal(e°zfl, e°2-1)) If [31> -1, then the consumer surplus when the health risk is present in the market is, ofl‘+l (G.6) CS,‘= -q,-,2 pi; e“ M: "1' ‘9 em‘ (%t— +1 —) l The expected value of the consumer surplus when risk information is present in the market is obtained by taking the expected value of (G.6): c"+ln '3 P EI-Qt-lz pt-l; ‘30 ‘30: £43) e“(—— B‘) +1] 1 ms) "g’l ’1 “0‘32”: ‘et-n) £_ p‘ E(e") B.+1 efl'el ’1 ‘0 “(41.1.9 £p_' 4.4192429 Bwl (G.7) '34-sz a”: G? The expected value of the consumer surplus when risk information is not present in the market is: (G3) E(CSto) g ‘410-12 P332 the eL‘ 9"” The expected value of the change in consumer suplus is thus: E(CS°)- E(CS )= n-1, e"‘ e ((;49) OB‘OI 'L“ ew’l’fin + 43-12 em’hn’] B,+1 BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY ”After Scare, Suit by Apple Farmers.“ flhe New 10:15 film cs, 29 November 1990, A22. Baumes, Harry S. Jr. and Roger K. Conway. & mpometfic Mggel of the US Apple Market. ERS Staff Report No: AGE8850110. Washington, DC: United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, 1985. Box, George ER and Gwilym M. Jenkins. Time Series allysis Eorecasting and Control. San Francisco: Holden Day, 1976. Buxton, Boyd. ”Economic Impact of Consumer Health Concerns About Alar on Apples.” Eruit and flee Nuts Situation and Outlook Yearmok TFS-ZSO, United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service (August 1989): 85-88. Caswell, Julie A. ed. Ecopomics of Food Safeg. New York: Elseiver Science Publishing Co., 1991. Chiang, Alpha C. Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics. 3rd ed., New York: McGraw Hill Book Company, 1984. Choi, Kwan E. and Helen H. Jensen. "Modelling the Effect of Risk on Food Demand." In W edited by Julie Caswell, New York: Elseiver Science Publishing Co., 1991. City of New York, Department of Consumer Affairs. Market Basket Report. New York, January 1980 - July.1991. Dalymple, Dana. ”Economic Aspects of Apple Marketing in the United States.” Ph.D. diss., Michigan State University, 1962. Deaton, Angus and John Muellbauer. Economics and Consumer Behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1980. Born, Young Sook. ”Pesticide Residues and Averting Behavior.” Raleigh: North Carolina State University, Division of Economics and Business, February 1991, [photocopy]. Fisher, A., L.G. Chestnut, and D.M. Violette. "The Value of Reducing Risks of Death: A Note on New Evidence.” Journal of Poligv Analysis and Management 8(1) (1989): 88- 100. 153 154 GAUSS System Version 2.1 for IBM PC-XT-AT-PS/2 & Compatibles. Aptech Systems Inc., Kent, Washington. Gibson, Richard. ”Apples With Alar Frightened Grocers More Than Buyers." M Street ,lgurnfl, 7 August 1989, B3. Gold, Allan. "Company Ends Use of Apple Chemical.“ flhe fig Yprk film es, 18 October 1989, A18. Guyton, William Preston. “Consumer Response to Risk Information: A Case Study of the Impact of Alar Scare on New York City Fresh Apple Demand.“ MS. Thesis, Michigan State University, 1990. Greene, William H. mnometric Analysis. New York: Macmillan Publishing Co., 1990. Halloran, John Mark. "Price Forecasting Model for Michigan Fresh Apples." MS. Thesis, Michigan State University, 1981. Hausman, J .A. ”Specification Tests in Econometrics.” Econometrig, 6(46) (November 1978): 1251-1271. Hoehn, John and Douglas Kreiger. Methods for Valuing Environmental Change. Staff Paper no. 88-30. East Lansing: Michigan State University, Department of Agricultural Economics, 1988. International Apple Institute. National and International Apple News. Mc. Lean, Virginia, January 1980 - July 1991. Ippolitto, Pauline and Richard A. Ippolitto. ”Measuring the Value of Life Saving From Consumer Reaction to New Information.” Journal of Public Egppmics, 25 (1984): 53-. 81. Judge, George G., W.E. Griffiths, R. Carter Hill, Helmut Lutkepth Tsoung-Chao Lee. Introduction to the 1th and fiactice of Econometrics. 2d ed. New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1988. Judge, George 6., WE. Griffiths, R. Carter Hill, Helmut Lutkepth Tsoung-Chao Lee. co and act'ce o Econometrics. 2d ed. New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1985. Kennedy, Peter. A Guide to Econometrics. 2d ed. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1985. Kmenta, Jan. Elements of Econometrics. 2d ed. New York: Macmillan Publishing Co., 1986. New York City, Department of Consumer Affairs. Market Basket Report. New York. O’Rourke, Desmond. ”Anatomy of a Disaster.” Agtibusiness, 6 (5) (1991): 417-424. 155 PC RATS (Regression Analysis Time Series) Version 3.1, VAR Econometrics Inc., Evanston, Il. Rescher, Nicholas. RE k: A Rhilomphimotl Introduction to the Theogt of Risk Evaluation and Mapagemept. New Yorszniversity Press of America, 1983. Sewell, Bradford H. and Robin M. Whyatt. ”Intolerable Risk: Pesticides in Our Children’s Food." Washington DC: Natural Resources Defense Council, 1989. Smith, Mark, Eileen O. van Ravenswaay and Stanley R. Thompson. ”Sales Loss Determination in Food Contamonation Incidents: An Application to Milk Bans in Hawaii." American Journal 01 Agticultural Economics, 70(3) (August 1988): $13-$20. State of New York, Department of Labor. Emploment Review. New York, January 1980 - July 1991. ”US to Bail Out Apple Growers." Chicago Tribune, 9 July 1989, C22. United States Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing Service. Fresh Fruit and Vegetable Arrivals in Eastern Cities. Washington, DC, January 1980 - July 1991. United States Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Marketing Service. Eresh Fruit and Vegetable Shipments in the United States. Washington, DC, January 1980 — July 1991. United States Departmant of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Current Population Reports. Series P25, Washington, DC, 1978 - 1988. United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Summag Population and Housing Characteristics. CPH-l, 1990. United States Department of Commerce, Bureau of Labor Statistics. CPI Detailed Report. Washington, DC, January 1980 - July 1991. van Ravenswaay, Eileen. "Consumer Perceptions of Health Risks in Food.” In luggsm' g Updgmtapdm' g of flblic Emblems and Eoliglgs-l990. Oak Brook, 11: Farm Foundation, 1990. van Ravenswaay, Eileen and John P. Hoehn. "The Impact of Health Risk on Food Demand: A Case Study of Alar and Apples." In Economics of Food Safeg, edited by Julie A. Caswell, New York: Elseiver Science Publishing Co., 1991. Willig, Robert D. ”Consumer Surplus Without Apology.” The American Economic Review, (September 1976): 589-597. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. ”Regression-Based Inference in Linear Time Series Models with Incomplete Dynamics." East Lansing: Michigan State University Department of Economics, August 1989, [photocopy].