, fix 1. a”, 132.2.» 1.3 flux... 9 #51”. LA. rut Raina}, ......».w...,,...‘... w . an .U... {aim a t 1 .. .. 53.11 . x5 . v. t i: 11 y .l. ER. tassewv . .5» t I . .T a»... .- r9: uhuze; In”. I .A . 11 8. Hanna]: :3... .V 1.. {a\ 5)». 9x Av‘li .1 1.7 A..I:VQK§§I9 £3 .‘2 h? €1.36 . t 2.. 2.2.. A a. " 53' v}: ' 3. o A :3 iii 1 ;u i 1.34 i 5.5! if? 3 ‘I u , , O 5 1.10.7. :‘f‘v‘ . vi! . : . Dvllg 3‘10“. slald. I“: . v9! 1. )t a 1 {.ti ‘1. 1: ho: 74".; ...f 1.. t‘ .2. wilt)... ’trlhvvulr.»‘ .2. ‘ 1:791? a... .Cvf. 31.1.13. 7 ,Pn. Innuuortut 55.51:? mmb b E Illllllmlllll1 Wists _ ‘ LIBRARY v' Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Global Competitive Advantage in the Ethical Pharmaceutical Industry: An Empirical Study. presented by Madhu Agrawal has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Doctor ofihflnsnndeegree in jusinesstministration jor professor Date May 9, 1995 MSU is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 A PLACE" RETURN BOXtoromavothbeMekthnywnoord. TOAVOID FINESrDtunonorbdorodntodm. F——_———__—l l DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE ‘1, ti? " r . SE??? memo! ""' ‘ ' fl] : :r {'3 .‘ i J83! ?‘5-‘ma ; .4' cfE-Z'LP?‘ HEEL! ; W 1,0:0 L -l—_l:] MSU loAn Affinndlvo AdionIEcpd Opportunity Imnwon m.” ‘ _ _ ,_ _ -L. — GLC GLOBAL COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE IN THE ETHICAL PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY By MADHU AGRAWAL A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Marketing and Logistics 1995 GD? gen; qtnmn anx Silmllidiz de mam ka\ hem /\ from E mch mhv emit: ABSTRACT GLOBAL COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE IN THE ETHICAL PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY: AN EMPIRICAL STUDY By MADHU AGRAWAL This study presents a theoretical and empirical investigation of the determinants of global competitive advantage in the ethical pharmaceutical industry. Two major research questions investigated in the study are: (1) Which country factors stimulate or inhibit a nation's pharmaceutical industry to be globally innovative? and (2) Which country factors stimulate or inhibit diffusion of pharmaceutical innovations into its markets? The motivation for doing the study derives from the growing concern in the past decade regarding national competitiveness issues in the new global economy. The global pharmaceutical industry is especially suitable for examination of country factors that affect competitiveness. Two path models - the Global Innovation Model (GIM) and the Global Diffusion Model (GDM) were tested using EQS - a structural equation modeling program on the mainframe. Data was obtained from secondary sources, mainly from the Scrip League Tables and United Nations publications. A sample of twenty—seven countries was used in the analysis. Besides a review of the literature, talks with industry experts and responses from a small-scale industry survey were also used as inputs in the study design. Several significant results were obtained. A country's economic, regulatory and market/industry environments were found to have significant effects on the ability of the industry to innovate. Diffusion was found to be significantly related to a country's environment for innovation. Industrialized and Developing countries were found to differ significantly with respect to the effects of various factors affecting competitiveness of the pharmaceutical industries in those countries. The study makes several contributions to the theoretical, empirical, managerial and public policy literature on global competitiveness; competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry; economic development issues; and global strategic management issues. Copyright by MADHU AGRAWAL 1995 To Sanjay , I. . QMMJ ' m, . r‘ $330.. V x , CI‘AOLL l '7; SJLZ€~ that: l)rcc resou [Taxi ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to thank all the members of my dissertation committee - Dr. Roger Calantone, Dr. Tamer Cavusgil, Dr. Robert Nason and Dr. Stan Fawcett - for their assistance and guidance in my dissertation research. I am especially grateful to Dr. Calantone for his invaluable moral and academic support throughout the course of my Ph.D. program. Without his constant guidance and encouragement, this work would not have been possible. I am thankful to Dr. Tamer Cavusgil and Dr. Robert Nason for their useful suggestions which greatly contributed to improving the study. Their support and encouragement during my four years in the program is also greatly appreciated. I would also like to extend my special thanks and gratitude to Ms. Sharon Lehman - Director of the Research Library of Parke-Davis for allowing me to use the library resources which provided much of the data used in the study. I also appreciate the help provided by Ms. Leona Williams - the librarian at Parke-Davis. Finally, I would like to acknowledge my family. My parents - for their innumerable sacrifices and unfailing support; my brothers - who have influenced and inspired me to attain higher goals; my in-laws - for their confidence and pride in my abilities; and my husband - Sanjay, without whose understanding, love and patience, this work would not have been possible. vi List of ' List of . Chaplet 5‘ ‘~v\'.1 Chialk ~_.__. TABLE OF CONTENTS List of Tables ...................................................................................... x List of Figures ..................................................................................... xii Chapter One: INTRODUCTION ................................................................ 1 1.1 Purpose of Study .................................................................. 1 1.2 Motivation for Study .............................................................. 1 1.3 Overview of Research Design and Conceptual Model ........................ 3 1.4 Expected Contributions of the Study ............................................ 5 1.5 Organization of the Study ........................................................ 7 Chapter Two: THE GLOBAL PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY ........................ 8 2.1 Present Status and Environment ................................................. 8 2.2 Evolution of the Global Industry ................................................ 12 2.3 Unique Characteristics of the Industry .......................................... 16 2.4 Determinants of Competitiveness in the Global Pharmaceutical Industry ............................................................................. 17 2.5 Summary ........................................................................... 19 Chapter Three: REVIEW OF LITERATURE ................................................. 20 3.1 National Competitiveness - Theoretical and Conceptual Perspectives ....... 20 3.1.1 Definition of National Competitiveness ............................. 21 3.1.2 Theory of Comparative Advantage ................................... 22 3.1.3 The Technology Factor Theory ...................................... 22 3.1.4 The Role of Government and Public Policy ......................... 24 3.2 Competitiveness in the Global Pharmaceutical Industry ..................... 28 3.2.1 Role of Regulation, R&D and Innovation ........................... 29 3.2 2 Pharmaceutical Diffusion and Competitiveness ..................... 32 3 2 3 Supply and Demand Factors in Pharmaceutical Competitiveness ....................................................... 35 3.2.4 Developing Country Competitiveness Issues ....................... 52 3.2.5 Conceptual Model of Global Pharmaceutical Competitiveness ........................................................ 55 3.3 Global Strategic Perspectives .................................................... 57 3 3 1 Core Competencies ..................................................... 57 3.3.2 Comparative Advantage-Based Competitive Advantage .......... 58 3 3 3 Collaborate to Compete ................................................ 61 vii (m A It Chapter Four: METHODOLOGY ............................................................... 63 4.1 Research Questions ................................................................ 63 4.1.1 Executive Survey ...................................................... 64 4.2 Model Development .............................................................. 66 4.2.1 The Global Innovation Model (GIM) ................................ 66 4.2.2 The Global Diffusion Model (GDM) ................................. 68 4.2.3 Constructs, Measures and Data Sources ............................. 68 4.2.4 Data Sources, Sample Size and Time Frame ........................ 72 4.3 Hypotheses ......................................................................... 74 4.4 Statistical Method of Analysis - EQS ............................................ 75 4.4.1 Uses of Structural Equation Modeling (SEM) ...................... 75 4.4.2 Steps in Structural Equation Modeling ............................... 78 4.4.3 Indirect Effects and Two-group Analysis ........................... 79 Chapter Five: RESULTS ......................................................................... 82 5.1 Global Innovation Model - Results .............................................. 82 5.1.1 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Market size on Innovation .............................................................. 83 5.1.2 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Industry focus on Innovation ............................................................... 90 5.1.3 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Industry growth on Innovation .............................................................. 93 5.1.4 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Industry Concentration on Innovation .......................................................... 96 5.1.5 Effect of Population, Approval time and Market size on Innovation ............................................................... 99 5.1.6 Effect of Population, Approval time and Industry focus on Innovation .............................................................. 102 5.1.7 Effect of Population, Approval time and Indusz growth on Innovation .............................................................. 102 5.1.8 Effect of Population, Approval time, Industry concentration and Foreign Commitment on Innovation ............................ 105 5.2 Group Differences - Industrialized and Developing Countries .............. 108 5.3 Significant Indirect Effects on Innovation and Global Competitiveness ................................................................... 1 16 5.4 Global Diffusion Model - Results ............................................... 118 5.5 Conclusions ........................................................................ 123 Chapter Six: CONCLUSIONS .................................................................. 127 6.1 Summary of Results ............................................................... 127 6.1.1 Determinants of Global Innovation ................................... 127 6.1.2 Global Innovation Factors for Industrialized versus Developing Country Industries ....................................... 128 6.1.3 Determinants of Global Diffusion .................................... 129 6.2 Implications of Study Results .................................................... 130 6.2.1 Managerial Implications ............................................... 130 6.2.2 Public Policy Implications ............................................. 138 6.3 Contributions of Study ........................................................... 143 6.3.1 Theoretical Contributions .............................................. 143 viii liSl‘ KPH) APPE 6.3.2 Empirical Contributions ............................................... 144 6.3.3 Methodological Contributions ................................ '. ....... 145 6.3.4 Managerial and Public Policy Contributions ........................ 146 6.4 Limitations of Study ............................................................... 146 6.5 Future Research Suggestions .................................................... 147 LIST OF REFERENCES ........................................................................ 149 APPENDD( A ..................................................................................... 159 APPENDIX B ..................................................................................... 191 Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table - Table - Table - Table - Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table T'dl‘l: Tal‘lh Tabl Tab}. Tab}. Ta; Tab; Tan; Tan“ Tabl Trbl Tab‘ Tabl Table 2.1 Table 3.1 Table 3.2 Table 3.3 Table 3.4 Table 4.1a Table 4.1b Table 4.2 Table 4.33 Table 4.3b Table 4.4a Table 4.4b Table 5.1 Table 5 .2 Table A] Table A.2 Table A3 Table A4 Table A5 Table A6 Table A.7 Table A8 Table A.9 Table A. 10 Table All Table A. 12 Table A. 13 Table A. 14 Table A.15 Table A. 16 Table A. 17 Table A. 18 Table A. 19 Table A.20 Table A.21 Table A.22 Table A.23 Table A.24 Table A.25 Table A.26 LIST OF TABLES Leading Pharmaceutical Markets for 1992 ..................................... 10 Overview of Studies on Global Pharmaceutical Competitiveness ........... 33 Overview of Studies on Global Pharmaceutical Diffusion .................... 36 Environmental Conditions and Global Pharmaceutical Competitiveness ................................................................... 53 Asian Pharmaceutical Markets by Size .......................................... 56 Constructs, Measures and Data Sources: The Global Innovation Model ............................................................................... 71 Constructs, Measures and Data Sources: The Global Diffusion Model ..... 73 Countries in Sample ............................................................... 74 Hypotheses: The Global Innovation Model .................................... 76 Hypotheses: The Global Diffusion Model ...................................... 76 Program runs for the Global Innovation Model .............................. 77 Program runs for the Global Diffusion Model ................................ 77 Significant Path Differences Between Industrialized and Developing Countries ........................................................................... 110 Summary of Results - Global Innovation Analysis ............................ 125 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 159 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 160 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 161 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 162 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 163 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 164 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 165 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 166 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 167 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 168 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 169 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 170 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 171 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 172 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 173 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 174 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 175 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 176 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 177 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 178 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 179 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 180 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 181 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 182 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 183 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 184 Table Table Table able Table Table Table Table Table Table Table Table able Table Tillie Tabb Tab} Table A.27 Table A.28 Table A.29 Table A.30 Table A.31 Table A.31 Table B.1 Table 3.2 Table B.3 Table B.4 Table B.5 Table B.6 Table 8.7 Table B.8 Table 8.9 Table B. 10 Table B.11 Table B. 12 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 185 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 186 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 187 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 188 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 189 Global Innovation Model ......................................................... 189 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 191 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 192 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 193 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 194 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 195 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 196 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 197 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 198 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 199 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 200 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 201 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 202 Figurell D1 Figure 1.23 Th Figure lib Tb; Hamil GT Figure 2.2 1m Figure 2.3 M Figure 3.1 D Figure 3.2 \l’ Figure 3.3 R1 Figure 3.4 T Figure 3.5 C < Figure 3.6 V. Figure 4.1 E» Figure 4.23 Ti l““lgure 4.2b. T“. Figure 4.33 Ti Flemish T; Fellini] Figures} Heiress HSHeSA fiwmij Flgure 56 fiflfiS] FlS‘ure 5.8 figure 5.9 lgure 5.10 mrnm memrr—nmzrmmmm Figure 1.1 Figure 1.2a Figure 1.2b Figure 2.1 Figure 2.2 Figure 2.3 Figure 3.1 Figure 3. 2 Figure 3.3 Figure 3. 4 Figure 3.5 Figure 3. 6 Figure 4.1 Figure 4. 2a Figure 4. 2b Figure 4.3a Figure 4.3b Figure 5.1 Figure 5. 2 Figure 5.3 Figure 5. 4 Figure 5.5 Figure 5.6 Figure 5.7 Figure 5.8 Figure 5.9 Figure 5.10 LIST OF FIGURES Determinants of Global Market Share in the Pharmaceutical Industry ...... 4 The Global Innovation Model .................................................... 6 The Global Diffusion Model ..................................................... 6 Global Sales by Corporate Nationality .......................................... 9 Important Milestones in the Evolution of the Global Pharmaceutical Inc .ustry ............................................................................. 13 NCE Introductions by US, Western Europe and Japan ...................... 18 Determinants of Global Market Share in the Pharmaceutical Industry ...... 38 World Consumption of Pharmaceuticals, 1992 ................................ 42 Risks in Pharmaceutical R&D .................................................... 44 Pricing Systems and Effects on R&D .......................................... 48 Conceptual Model of Global Pharmaceutical Competitiveness ............... 57 Value-Added Chain for Pharmaceuticals ........................................ 60 Executive Survey .................................................................. 65 The Global Innovation Model .................................................... 67 The Global Diffusion Model ..................................................... 67 The EQS Model for Global Innovation ......................................... 80 The EQS Model for Global Diffusion ........................................... 81 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Market size on Innovation ............. 84 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Industry focus on Innovation ......... 91 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Industry growth on Innovation ....... 94 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Industry Concentration on ............ Innovation ......................................................................... 97 Effect of Population, Approval time and Market size on Innovation ........ 100 Effect of Population, Approval time and Industry focus on Innovation ......................................................................... 103 Effect of Population, Approval time and Industry growth on Innovation .......................................................................... 104 Effect of Population, Approval time, Industry concentration and Foreign Commitment on Innovation ....................................... 106 Significant Indirect Effects ....................................................... 1 17 Global Diffusion Model ........................................................... 120 xii l.l T’L'RP The n‘ competitive a, research quet (ll CHAPTER ONE INTRODUCTION 1.1 PURPOSE QF STUDY The main objective of the study was to examine the determinants of global competitive advantage in the ethical1 pharmaceutical industry. Specifically, the two main research questions of the study were: (1) Which country factors stimulate or inhibit a nation's pharmaceutical industry to be globally innovative? (2) Which country factors stimulate or inhibit diffusion of pharmaceutical innovations (N CEs)2 into its markets? The above research questions were developed after a review of the literature, talking to industry experts, and from the responses of an executive survey carried out to determine the factors affecting global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. 12 W National competitiveness has become one of the central preoccupations of government and industry in every nation, especially so in the US. The competitiveness of the US economy in the global market became a growing concern during the 19803, due to sustained deterioration in the US trade deficit. The loss of market share in products such as 1 An "ethical" pharmaceutical is one that is available only through prescription. Ethical products can be either patented or non patented (i.e., generic). 2 An NCE is a drug for which the active ingredient has not been previously marketed (approved) for use in a drug product microelectronics, an industry thought invulnerable to foreign competition, began to raise questions regarding the overall international competitiveness of the US economy. In 1990, the US Senate Committee on Finance identified three industries which were important for future US competitiveness in the global economy. The Committee directed the US International Trade Commission to conduct investigations on these three advanced-technology manufacturing industries of which one was the pharmaceutical industry. The global pharmaceutical industry is a multinational industry that is highly regulated, capital intensive and driven by large R&D expenditures. The world market for ethical pharmaceuticals in 1992 was estimated to be US $ 163.4 billion (Scrip Magazine 1994). Supported by an ever-increasing demand for health care, world production of pharmaceuticals has grown at an exceptional pace throughout most of the post-war period. Today nearly 60 countries have annual production levels of at least $100 million (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). World consumption of pharmaceutical preparations has doubled between 1975 and 1990 with the world's per capita consumption of drugs increasing almost 70 percent in the same years. Very few industries can boast of such an impressive growth record. However, other than the above factors, there is a more important reason for examining factors affecting competitiveness of the pharmaceutical industry in different countries. The industry is of great social and public importance in all the countries. A flood of life-saving drugs has emerged from the world's pharmaceutical laboratories over the past four decades. By combating many fatal diseases and eradicating others, drug producers have helped to alter mortality patterns in many parts of the world. 1.3 RIEW FREEARHDEI AD PTALM E For the purpose of developing the conceptual framework, the research design and the hypotheses, three streams of literature were reviewed. These were: (1) Theoretical and Conceptual Perspectives on National Competitiveness, (2) Competitiveness in the Global Pharmaceutical Industry, and (3) Global Strategic Management Perspectives. The conceptual model used to develop the statistical path models in the study is illustrated in Figure 1.1. The model illustrates a number of supply and demand related factors that affect global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. The demand for ethical pharmaceuticals is determined by demographic and socioeconomic factors. Government policies and programs also affect the demand for drugs, directly or indirectly. An important factor affecting the supply of ethical pharmaceuticals is R&D activity, i.e., the level and productivity of R&D spending. Government actions ranging from macroeconomic policies, treatment of product liability, and regulatory controls exert direct and indirect effects (positive and negative) on the ability of firms and the industry as a whole to produce pharmaceuticals. Besides a review of the literature, talks with industry experts and responses from an executive survey conducted before the actual data collection, provided insights into development of the constructs and measures for the study. Data was obtained from secondary sources, mainly from the Scrip League Tables and governmental publications such as the United Nations. Pharmaceutical industry data for a total of twenty-seven countries was used in this study. Of these, fifteen are industrialized countries and twelve are developing countries. Two-group analysis will be done to examine differences in competitiveness factors between the industrialized (I) and developing (D) nation pharmaceutical industries. The statistical package used to analyze the models was EQS - a structural equation modeling program on the mainframe. The two path models developed are illustrated in SOUrCe Figure 1.1: Determinants of Global Market Share in the Pharmaceutical Industry Global Market Share Marketing! Consumer information R&D Activity Socio nomic External 900 Financing factors Demographic factors I Profits I‘— Health c are / Reimbursement and other health care programmes V acroeeonomoc policies Profit controls 00st Containmen' Tax Policies IPR Technology Source: USITC (1991) Education '15 ' ro- v Regulatory Marketing (in particular . - Iicies Expertise R&D productivity) Indirect & Direct Funding Basic Research Development Education Other infrastructure Figure iheG slut \Kl Figures 1.2a and 1.2b. They will be referred to as the Global Innovation Model (GIM) and the Global Diffusion Model (GDM) in this study. 1.4 RIB TI Theoretical, empirical, and methodological contributions are expected from the study. In addition important managerial and public policy implications of the study results will also be examined. Theoretical contributions to several streams of literature are expected. Theoretical concepts from the literature on - national competitiveness, pharmaceutical innovation and diffusion, economic development literature, and the global strategic literature are combined in this study. Significant empirical contributions to the global competitiveness research on the pharmaceutical industry are expected since this study uses a far larger sample of countries, a more comprehensive model, and greater sophistication in statistical method of analysis than previous studies done in the area. Managerial implications from the study results will be many. Strategic management issues both from the perspective of industrialized country MNCs and developing country MNCs will be discussed. These implications will be discussed with respect to type of core competencies that global pharmaceutical firms should develop; the various types of comparative advantages of countries that firms should exploit for developing competitive advantage; and the strategic choices that firms should make when collaborating with international firms. Public Policy implications are expected to be extremely important since the pharmaceutical industry is heavily regulated in most countries and such regulations have far-reaching impact on its competitiveness. Public policy implications with respect to the economic environment, the regulatory environment, and the market/industry environment Figure 1.2a: The Global Innovation Model ‘ Economic Foreign Mkt Environment Investment 4. (outbound) + + Innovation + 4» Global . , investment C°mP°uuw BOSS Regulation ' + . + Mitt/Industry ‘ Structure Figure 1.2b: The Global Diffusion Model Wm Foreign Mkt Envrronrnent Investment (inbound) a}. Market + . I . . . I I I Global + Regulation - Potential - - ' - - - Innovation Mitt/Industry Structure for pharmucel for industnulii pharmaceutic; eomperitio Wuhwr Cl competiti' are reviei C teehniqu deveIOp m0dels analysi lmplie 0f the for pharmaceuticals will be explored on the basis of the study results. Recommendations for industrialized and developing country policy makers will be made with respect to their pharmaceutical industries in the global economy. 1.5 QBQANIZAIIQN QF THE STUDY The study has six chapters. Chapter 2 presents an overview of the nature of global competition in the pharmaceutical industry and discusses its evolution in the post World War 11 period. Chapter 3 reviews the literature on national competitiveness, global pharmaceutical competitiveness, and global strategic management. Studies from these streams of literature are reviewed to develop the constructs and hypotheses used in the research. Chapter 4 presents the research questions; the statistical models and statistical technique; and the constructs, measures and data sources used in the study. Hypotheses developed to analyze the relationships are also discussed. Chapter 5 is the results. Results from the global innovation and global diffusion models are discussed. Indirect effects are also examined. The results of the two-group analysis of industrialized (I) and developing country (D) groups are also discussed. Chapter 6 presents the summary of results; managerial and public policy implications of the study results; the theoretical, empirical and methodological contributions of the study; limitations of study; and concludes with suggestions for future research. This global envi the global \V orld \\' ; Phanmice global pl chapter. In) 1—4 FEgula Pfimm CHAPTER TWO THE GLOBAL PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTRY This chapter has five sections. Section One presents an overview of the current global environment for pharmaceutical products. Section Two traces the development of the global pharmaceutical industry and the changes taking place especially in the post- World War H period. Section Three discusses some of the unique characteristics of the pharmaceutical industry. Section Four examines the determinants of competitiveness in the global pharmaceutical industry. Finally, Section Five provides a summary of the present chapter. 2.1 R T AD R MET The global pharmaceutical industry is a multinational industry that is highly regulated, capital intensive and driven by large R&D expenditures. The industry is primarily privately owned and is technologically sophisticated. The world market for ethical pharmaceuticals (excluding China and the former Soviet Union) in 1992 was estimated to be US $163.4 billion (Scrip Magazine 1994). In 1990, the top 80 pharmaceutical firms worldwide accounted for about 90 percent of the global sales of ethical pharmaceuticals. Of these 80 firms, US based companies accounted for approximately 40 percent of global sales, European based firms accounted for another 40 percent and Japan accounted for 20 percent of the world sales (USITC 1991, Figure 2.1). Source: Scri Th< (\th pet Ci mm \\‘m\ estimate: seen fro: had the Eight V Merck eSIlm; Figure 2.1: Global Sales by Corporate Nationality 20% Japan 40%6 Western Europe 40% USA Source: Scrip League Tables The largest pharmaceutical market for 1992 was the US — it accounted for twenty- nine per cent of the world market. The second—largest market was Japan with eighteen per cent world market share. Table 2.1 shows the ten leading markets in 1992 along with their estimated market value, percentage share of world market and percentage growth. It can be seen from the table that two of the developing countries, namely Brazil and South Korea had the highest growth rates for 1992. Of the fifteen leading companies worldwide in pharmaceutical sales for 1992/ 1993, eight were US based, two were UK based, two German based and three were Swiss. Merck & Co. of USA was the leading pharmaceutical company worldwide with an estimated sales of $ 8,214.5 million (Scrip Magazine 1994). Supported by an ever-increasing demand for health care, world production of pharmaceuticals has grown at an exceptional pace throughout most of the post-war period. Today nearly 60 countries have annual production levels of atleast $ 100 million (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). The bulk of world production is however confined to only a few countries. 10 Table 2.1: Leading Pharmaceutical Markets for 1992 Market Est. market value % world market % growth (pounds billions) US 32.6 29 6 Japan 19.9 18 3 Germany 9.5 9 5 France 8.2 7 8 Italy 6.8 6 5 UK 3 .6 3 13 Spain 3.0 3 11 Canada 2.4 2 9 Brazil 1.9 2 19 South Korea 1.8 2 15 Others 20.9 19 15 ‘5 The I. first emerge. Netherlands. pharmaceut; production. m’otit‘ths of 1 \Vorlt WmSlObfl more than s< The dm'elor in Japan a Spectacula industnaliz Du consolidar proliferat- Consolidg bElllg gqu O EurOPtTan thew cor cOmmitm 11 The leaders continue to be those countries where modern pharmaceutical production first emerged: Belgium, France, the Federal Republic of Germany, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States. The pharmaceutical industry in developing countries accounts for a fifth of the world production. China is the largest producer among the developing countries, accounting for two-fifths of this group's total in 1988 (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). World consumption of pharmaceutical preparations (in constant 1980 US dollars) was $ 70 billion in 1975 but had more than doubled, to $ 150 billion by 1990. However, more than seventy per cent of all pharmaceuticals are sold in developed market economies. The developing countries account for less than a fifth. Drug usage is growing most rapidly in Japan and North America. The growth of the Japanese drug market has been spectacular. The country's per capita consumption was already the highest of all industrialized countries in 1975 and has continued to rise since then. During the past decade, the pharmaceutical industry has undergone increasing consolidation. Domestic and international mergers, joint ventures, and strategic alliances proliferated in the global pharmaceutical industry in the 19803. The main reason for the consolidation is the increase in R&D costs in recent years. Manufacturer's profits are also being squeezed by increasing pressure from national governments to contain health costs. Of the top ten leading companies in R&D expenditures, for 1993, seven were European and three were US based. The average proportion of sales allocated to R&D by these companies was 15.9 per cent. Of the top ten companies in terms of foreign commitment (percent share of foreign to total sales), European companies dominated the list with only one US company in the top ten (Scrip Magazine 1994). Figur pharmaceuu One inclusm' we chemical 11 .\l-. found th pharmacc' Pharmac Producti. one oft small d OVerse techn w / (:1 I't 12 2.2 EVQLUIIQE QE THE QLQBAL 131211513! Figure 2.2 illustrates the important milestones in the evolution of the global pharmaceutical industry1 . One of the earliest milestones in the development of the global pharmaceutical industry was the Pre-World War H development and commercial marketing by the German chemical industry of a number of synthetically derived pharmaceutical products. Many of the early chemical companies, such as those in Switzerland and Germany, found that their technology to make synthetic dyes was readily transferable to pharmaceuticals, resulting in the development and commercialization of a number of new pharmaceutical products between 1908 and World War H. Advances in pharmaceutical production technology were also made during this time. The Swiss industry had established facilities early in the United States becoming one of the first to become truly multinational in an effort to compensate for their relatively small domestic market. After World War H, however, the US industry rapidly expanded overseas. The pharmaceutical industry worldwide became truly global in scope after World War 11. Several interrelated factors contributed to this trend. Significant advances in technology which led to the discovery of newer, more effective therapy took place in this period. Manufacturing know-how increased, enabling production of pharmaceuticals in huge quantities. Demand for medications increased world over because of their greater effectiveness and availability. This was coupled with increase in economic growth leading to greater purchasing power of consumers, helped by national health insurance systems in some countries. lSee Smith (1983) for a review 1899 1906 1908 1914 1931 1935 1939 1941 1951 196 197 197 191 191 Adapted fj 13 Figure 2.2: Important Milestones in the Evolution of the Global Pharmaceutical Industry 1899 - Discovery of Aspirin 1906 - Pure Food and Drug Act (USA) 1908 1914 - World War I Discovery of Salversan (Germany) 1931 1935 1939 - World War II FDA established (USA) Discovery of Sulfa Drugs 1940 - US spends $3 million on Penicillin research 1950-1960 - Multinational expansion by US firms 1962 - Kefauver-Harris Amendment to the FDCA 1975 - Revision of Japanese investment policies 1975-1985 - Dramatic rise in biotech firms in US 1989 - Mergers/Acquisitions 1990-1995 - Patents on approximately 200 products to expire in the US Adapted from USITC (1991) 14 However to better understand the tremendous changes taking place in the period, the post World War II period can be divided into three important eras, namely, (a) 1940— 1960: The Golden Era (b) 1960-1980: Era of Regulation and (c) 1980 - to the present: Era of Strategic Alliances which are discussed below (Agrawal 1993). l - : 1d E Several synthetic compounds were discovered in this period. The availability of a wide range of synthetic compounds and the advent of public health care systems coupled with a surge in economic prosperity and political stability, created a tremendous grth in the international pharmaceutical market (Keller and Smith 1969). During this period, the US drug firms dramatically increased their investment abroad. Between 1950 and 1959, the value of total US. investment abroad rose from twelve billion dollars to almost thirty billion dollars. A prominent observer during this period dubbed this phenomenon of frenzied international expansion as the " gold rush" (Moskowitz 1961). The key factor in the early success of the American drug companies was their technological leadership. A number of important pharmacologic innovations in United States, particularly in the antibiotic and corticosteroid fields, produced a virtual revolution in the pharmaceutical marketplace. Technological leadership coupled with adequate resources and a lack of organized competition enabled many of the larger American drug companies to secure important market positions. By 1960, the US. lead in the drug export race, with Switzerland, Great Britain, West Germany, and France also in the race (Chemical Engineering News 1960). Waugh This period was characterized by increasing discontent of the public with the industry especially in the US and Britain leading to greater regulatory controls over the pmuiccs ( iugx"ar 1 being in 1961 a] amend: bt'reag relate srnaE £11 15 practices of drug firms. Cries of "unethical promotion," "excess profits'" "soaring costs of drugs," and the like were commonly heard (Chemical Engg News 1961). The thalidomide disaster2 served as the catalyst for increased regulatory reforms being implemented (Smith 1983). The US passed the Kefauver-Harris amendment in 1961 which imposed serious regulatory controls over the American based companies. This amendment made pharmaceutical research a more expensive and time consuming process by requiring substantial evidence of efficacy for approval of new drugs. Germany introduced new regulations concerning advertising of pharmaceuticals and related products during this period. Stringent governmental rules discouraged several smaller firms from venturing abroad in the 19605 and 19705. T t' The e ' In the past few years, the traditional strengths of the pharmaceutical companies - patented products, pricing flexibility, and steady innovation - have begun to erode. Today, it costs anywhere from a hundred million to a hundred and twenty-five million dollars to develop a new drug, which is up from about ten million dollars just twenty years ago (Financial World 1989). These developments have led companies to form strategic alliances with each other (James 1983; Financial World 1989; USITC 1991). This trend of acquisitions and mergers is expected to continue in the future, in an attempt to reduce R&D costs and duplication of efforts. Japanese firms are also moving to set up joint ventures and subsidiaries as their home market gets saturated. Japan already has two drug firms in the world top twenty, and has overtaken America as the world's most innovative drug producer, ranked by the number of new drugs (The Economist 1988). 2Thalidomide was a tranquilizer-sedative marketed by Chemie Grunenthal in West Germany as a non- prescription drug. The product was distributed for approximately 3 years before Dr. Leng, a pediatrician at the University of Hamburg, discovered and reported to the company that it caused phocomelia, a birth defect in infants. By this time, several thousand infants had been affected. detailed im'c accomplishn world's laho' eradicatingl the world. As operate. ' safety or country, 11161. scientir‘ teams, t 10013 c COmpa Writ) 133115 lee on]! NM 131”: Sn 16 2.3 HA TER T F E I D TRY There are a number of reasons why the global pharmaceutical industry merits a detailed investigation. One is that although the industry's history is comparatively brief, its accomplishments are impressive. A flood of life-saving drugs has emerged from the world's laboratories over the past four decades. By combating many fatal diseases and eradicating others, drug producers have helped to alter mortality patterns in many parts of the world. A second reason is the highly politicized environment in which drug companies operate. Their performance, whether measured in terms of product development, prices, safety or efficacy, is a vital determinant of health. Regulations vary from country to country, but all governments intervene extensively to ensure that national standards are met. A third noteworthy feature of the industry is that it combines a unique blend of scientific knowledge, manufacturing skills and marketing tactics. At one end are large teams of organic chemists, biochemists, biophysicists and pharrnacologists who use all the tools of modern science in their search for new drugs. At the other are huge - and highly competitive - networks for distribution and promotion which operate in markets where performance is closely monitored by governments. Sandwiched between these two crucial parts of the industry is the production of drugs. A fourth characteristic of this industry is the extent of internationalization and diversity which exists. A great deal of the industry's research and production occurs in only a few countries. However the markets for drugs are global. The types of pharmaceutical firms are just as varied and diverse as their markets. In addition to the multinationals and their subsidiaries, there are many small and medium-sized firms, niche producers, and other specialists identified by their research or marketing strengths or by the Specific types of drugs they produce. 1er 1'5 con: represents : pharmaceut: 19911. 17 Finally, the pharmaceutical industry is especially important for the United States. The US continues to be the world leader in discovering and developing new medicines and represents the world's largest single market for pharmaceuticals. In 1991, US pharmaceutical exports exceeded imports by about S 1 billion (US Industrial Outlook 1991). 2.4 ETER A T F MP TI E E I PHARMACEUTICAL INDUSTR! A study conducted by the US International Trade Commission in 1991 on the global competitiveness of the US pharmaceutical industry concluded that: (1) The competitiveness of the US pharmaceutical industry as well as of those in other countries, depends largely on the ability of firms within the industry to develop innovative products, and innovation in turn, depends on the ability to finance R&D. (2) Government policies, both domestic and foreign have a more significant effect on the level of industry innovation than many of the other factors studied (USITC 1991). The USITC study concluded that the US pharmaceutical industry has maintained a high degree of competitiveness during 1980-90, as compared with the industries in Western Europe and Japan. The study found that the US industry was a leader in innovation during 1975-89, developing the majority of the globally successful products introduced during this time period. This is in contrast to the conclusions published in the report of a study done by the National Academy of Sciences (NAB 1983) to assess the competitive position of the US pharmaceutical industry in the world economy. The study found a declining trend in the US share of R&D expenditures and drugs entering clinical trials and predicted further decline in US shares of pharmaceutical introductions, sales and exports. Fun? For examp'. whereas L'S SCllp - \‘ilflt‘ in which L’S Figur Western Eur Europe shot! an Upward t. :1 “CF. Introduced 18 Further, more recent data indicates that Japanese companies may be catching on. For example, for the years 1982 - 1993, Japan introduced 158 new chemical entities whereas US introduced 123 new chemical entities in the same period (Author‘s estimates, Scrip - various issues). Although these NCEs do not represent globally successful NCEs2 in which US is still a leader, the data should still be a cause for concern. Figure 2.3 illustrates the pattern of NCE introduction from 1961 to 1990 by US, Western Europe and Japan. The number of NCEs originating from the US and Western Europe show a declining trend, whereas the number of NCEs originating from Japan show an upward trend for the past decade. Figure 2.3 NCE Introductions by US, Western Europe and Japan I 1961-70 0) O O I I [11971-80 I 1981-90 # NCE: Introduced LS W.EUF10PE JAPAN Source: Author's estimates based on various sources 2 A globally successful NCE or global NCE is defined as an NCE that has been approved/marketed in at least seven of the major pharmaceutical country markets, i.e., France, Germany, Japan, Italy, Switzerland, UK and the US. It is dontinr industry he» recent past marketing t; tdevelop ne markets. 19 2.5 SJLMMARX The global pharmaceutical industry is highly multinational and research intensive. It is dominated by companies from the US, Western Europe and Japan. Over the years, the industry has faced increasing regulatory pressures from national governments and in the recent past has been characterized by mergers and strategic alliance formation. The industry combines a unique blend of scientific knowledge, manufacturing skills and marketing tactics. Competitiveness in the global industry depends on ability to innovate (develop new drugs) and overcome market and regulatory barriers of varying country markets. This protided the design - incl for drawing literature at Competitii (1101131 Sty; Ethel-1m the L's ( Suilalne Imcroel raise qt f0? 51111 expl'dir CHAPTER THREE REVIEW OF LITERATURE This chapter reviews the theoretical, conceptual and empirical literature that provided the basis for development of the conceptual framework for the study; the research design - including the constructs, measures and hypotheses used in the research study; and for drawing implications and conclusions from the study results. Three streams of literature are discussed below: (1) Theoretical and Conceptual Perspectives on National Competitiveness, (2) Competitiveness in the Global Pharmaceutical Industry and (3) Global Strategic Perspectives. 3.1 MP I E - T RE AL AND E E T National competitiveness has become one of the central preoccupations of government and industry in every nation, especially so in the US. The competitiveness of the US economy in the global market became a growing concern during the 19808, due to sustained deterioration in the US trade deficit. The loss of market share in products such as microelectronics, an industry many thought invulnerable to foreign competition, began to raise questions regarding the overall intemational competitiveness of the US economy. Yet for all the discussion, debate and writing on the topic, there is still no persuasive theory to explain national competitiveness (Porter 1990). 20 competitive: rates. intere function ot competitix'e: relations. 1’ competitiver "cor cont vshi (Cc Th. fact that c. Variable t: indicator Variables t lEVeL 11 etampr or firn SCCIOr; Sll’eng Wage. comp exam r dildn 21 3.1.1 Definition of National Competitiveness An accepted definition of the term "competitiveness" is lacking. Some see national competitiveness as a macroeconomic phenomenon, driven by variables such as exchange rates, interest rates, and government deficits. Others argue that competitiveness is a function of cheap and abundant labor. Another popular explanation for national competitiveness is differences in management practices, including management-labor relations. Porter (1990) identifies productivity as the major determinant of a nation's competitiveness. According to the President's Commission on Industrial Competitiveness, "competitiveness is the degree to which a nation can, under free and fair market conditions, produce goods and services that meet the test of international markets while simultaneously maintaining or expanding the real incomes of its citizens" (Commission on Industrial Competitiveness, 1985). The lack of clarity on the definition of national competitiveness is due in part to the fact that competitiveness is a multidimensional concept that cannot be reduced to a single variable or indicator. A second difficulty arises from the fact that it is difficult to consider indicators of competitive position separately, without reference to underlying causal variables (Hatzichronoglou 1991). Although it is appropriate to consider international competitiveness at the national level, it has a different meaning when applied at the industry or individual firm level. For example, at the sectoral level, competitiveness may be defined as the ability of an industry or firm to sustain and/or expand its market position. Competitiveness at the national sectoral levels are intertwined, however, since the former depends on the competitive strength of firms and/or industries to generate productivity levels needed to support high wages and hence higher standards of living in the economy. Similarly sector competitiveness depends on appropriate policy at the national level, that would, for example, provide a framework for the promotion of high levels of skill through education and maintenance and/or development of infrastructure. 22 Bruce Scott of the Harvard Business School has defined national competitiveness "a nation state's ability to produce, distribute and service goods in the international economy in competition with goods and services produced by other countries, and to do so in a way that earns a rising standard of living" (Scott and Lodge 1985). There are three critical aspects to this definition. First, it is mom, that is the export performance of a nation is considered relative to that of others. Second, it is a W concept, that is the ability of a nation to earn a higher standard of living by production and marketing skills, rather than by international borrowings. Third, it is a M15; concept as it evaluates the manner in which a nation seeks to increase and distribute its welfare over time, given its international and domestic commitments. 3.1.2 Theory of Comparative Advantage This theory also refened to as the classical theory explains the success of nations in particular industries based on so-called factors of production such as land, labor and natural resources. Nations gain factor-based comparative advantage in industries that make intensive use of the factors they possess in abundance. Classical theory, however, has been overshadowed in advanced industries and economies by the globalization of competition and the power of technology. 3.1.3 WES!!! Although there may be little agreement on the definition of competitiveness, there is general consensus in the more recent literature that national competitiveness depends on much more than the cost of production and prices of output. Technology is increasingly recognized as the most important determinant to achieving competitive advantage in the global economy (Niosi 1991; Scott 1985; Porter 1990; Ernst and O'Connor 1989). Recent studies on international competitiveness emphasize the central role played by technology in — determining been empha~ Gomullta t ‘1‘ 1985'. Ernst . The: as the techno The 11 innovative a; in output an command h countries wi level of Val Louis Emrn "Tc har dll‘ th'i ins. \V Particuja Compare natiOhs 1 the imp “21110” S ma9Var 23 determining the world market share (Davis 1991; Dosi and Soete 1991; Scott and Lodge 1985; Ernst and Connor 1989; Porter 1990). The role of technology and innovation in economic growth of a nation has long been emphasized by industrial economists since the time of Schumpeter. Posner (1961), Gomulka (1971) and Cornwall (1976) developed this approach into what they referred to as the technology gap theory. The technology gap theorists relate the technological level of a country to its lelel_of W. A high level of innovative activity means a high share of "new" goods in output and an extensive use of "new" techniques in production. Since "new" goods command high prices and "new" techniques imply high productivity, it follows that countries with comparatively higher level of innovative activities also tend to have a higher level of value-added per worker, or GDP per capita, than other countries. According to Louis Emmerij, President of OECD, "Today, oligopolistic competition and strategic interaction rather than the "invisible hand" of market forces, condition comparative advantage and the international division of labor. The introduction of new technologies plays an important role in this process. Firms as much as nations are striving to utilize technology as an instrument of global competition.."(Emst and O'Connor 1989, p. 8). When one looks at any national economy, there are striking differences among a nation's industries in competitive success. International advantage is often concentrated in particular industry segments. In many industries and segments of industries, the competitors with true international competitive advantage are based in only a few nations. Porter's study (1990) examined high-technology industries in ten important trading nations to investigate why nations gain competitive advantage in particular industries and the implications for company strategy and national economies. The study found that a nation's competitiveness in a particular industry depends on the capacity of its industry to innovate and upgrade. Companies from such nations gain advantage against the world's best compc domestic rit qu competitite' conditions demandt‘. R Differences in addition 1 The challenger higher lEV create an . 1 COmpetit [CC 1100 l( andtcw comp-:- llaVe 1 ‘11 th. 3.1.4 30%: 10Wa 24 best competitors because of pressure and challenge. They benefit from having strong domestic rivals, aggressive home-based suppliers, and demanding local customers. Four broad attributes of a nation contribute to innovation and subsequent national competitiveness, both individually as well as a system. These attributes are: Factor conditions (labor, infrastructure, etc.); Demand conditions (nature of home-market demand); Related and Supporting Industries; and Firm strategy, structure and rivalry. Differences in national values, economic structures, institutions, and histories all contribute in addition to competitive success. The study also concluded that the proper role of government is as a catalyst and a challenger; it is to encourage-or even push-companies to raise their aspirations and move to higher levels of competitive performance. Government policies that succeed are those that create an environment in which companies can gain competitive advantage. The literature on international technology transfer also provides some insights on competitiveness in the global economy (Robinson 1991). Competitiveness in high technology industries depends on: (a) Supply of technology, (b) Demand for technology and (c) Intermediaries and linking mechanisms. 3.1.4 W The role of government and public policy in a nation's effort to achieve international competitiveness has been a subject of much debate. Three major policy recommendations have been offered in the literature as a whole: (1) the activist industrial policy perspective, (2) the managed trade perspective and (3) the neoclassical or liberal economics perspective. 3.1.4.1 WW1: The advocates of industrial policies in the early 19805 recommended an active government role to enable all industries within an advanced economy to shift production towards higher value-added and more competitive outputs (Wachter and Wachter 1982; Magaziner z industries ft agreements 1 out to ease a from impor employees t subsidies. l abroad. Ma administer agreement €01'Emme Goldstein solely to 1 abroad. 1 1&8111C110n 113116 pen 5993' 011 Planned p 3.1.4, 3 11 and mam, Competirir HMSOPQU 25 Magaziner and Reich 1982; Adams and Klein 1982; Johnson 1984). For declining industries for example, proponents of the activist industrial policies recommend that agreements between the US and governments of other advanced nations should be worked out to ease adjustment of less competitive firms by granting subsidies as well as protection from imports for a limited period, as needed. For emerging businesses with high-skilled employees characterized by rapid technological change, the US government should provide subsidies, loan guarantees, and tax benefits to lure them to locate at home rather then abroad. 3.1.4.2 T d d P iv Managed trade can be broadly defined as trade that is controlled, directed, or administered by government policies and conducted by either bilateral or multilateral agreements (U SITC 1991). The proponents of managed trade recommend some form of government involvement in high-technology industries (Reich 1983; Tyson 1990; Goldstein and Krasner 1984). They suggest that the fate of these industries cannot be left solely to market forces, particularly in the presence of activist government intervention abroad. They recommend active intervention in the form of export subsidies and import restrictions. Both the activist industrial policy and managed trade proponents use Japanese trade performance to support their views since they consider Japan's success as a case study of how a country can realize its trade-related goals through extensive, but carefully planned protectionism. 3.1.4.3 W1: The proponents of the liberal or neoclassical perspective reject the activist industrial and managed trade policy recommendations for enhancing the US economy's international competitiveness (President's Commission on Industrial Competitiveness 1985; Dixit 1986; Hatsopoulos, Krugman and Summers 1988; Porter 1990; Landau 1990). They argue that pursuing su. about the ct economists 3 economy an in the econo and increase For e national con maintain an . higher sat’ir horizons on R&D. 3.1.4.4 Sir C9mpetitit lllllm‘atim T1 2m“emptir. innmatte: - 0r haw. gOVEmU— regularic 1 iYmOVau Robfirtg Thoma. 26 pursuing such a strategic trade policy would require vast, unknown amounts of information about the economy and extemalities associated with interventionist policy. Also, most economists believe that such policies could result in raised costs for other sectors within the economy and in trade wars. The liberal economics view is perhaps the most accepted view in the economics literature of promoting the US economy's international competitiveness and increase the standard of living. For example, Porter (1990) recommends the following government initiatives for national competitiveness: maintain a strong antitrust policy to foster domestic competition; maintain an open trade policy and avoid devaluation to boost exports; create incentives for higher savings and allow interest rates to fall to encourage investment and longer time horizons on R&D projects; and fund university research centers to rejuvenate national R&D. 3.1.4.4 ndu ' v ' n i I' Since innovation drives technological growth and therefore industrial competitiveness, it is important to look at the effect regulation can have on industrial innovation processes. There have been more studies done on the factors endogenous to the firm in attempting to explain innovative success or failure; that is they have considered the innovation process more or less exclusively from the point of view of what managers have - or have not - done and by and large neglected external factors such as the role of government (Rothwell and Zegveld 1981). The studies that have examined the impact of regulation on industrial innovation processes are reviewed below. Perhaps more has been written about the effects of regulation on the rate of innovation in pharmaceuticals than in any other single sector of the industry (Hauptrnan and Roberts 1987; Young 1982; Grabowski and Vernon 1976; Grabowski, Vernon and Thomas 1978; Hansen 1979; Peltzman and DiRaddo 1980; Peltzman, May and Trirnble 1982:1119; 1916; Lasai 1974'. Schar regulation o watershed. significantlt obsert'ed dil 1963 Amenr A st Chcmicals it 90111 quanti‘ also indica beginning ; Amefldmer the United “‘35 Opera 1116 rare 0'. 10 indlCatc H. quality. ‘ Stm’ard \ 27 1982; Wiggins 1981; 1983; Brownlee 1979;C1ymer 1970; 1975; Cooper 1969; 1976; Jaffe 1976; Lasagna 1969; 1972; Lasagna and Wardell 1975; Mitchell and Link 1976; Sarett 1974; Schankerrnan 1976; Schwartzman 1976; Wardell 1973; 1974) Much that has been written has focused on the impact of the 1962 Kefauver-Harris Amendments to the US Food, Drug and Cosmetics Act1 . Most analyses of the effects of regulation on innovation in the US drug industry have treated the 1962 Amendments as a watershed. According to Peltzman (1973), for example, the 1962 Amendments significantly reduced the flow of New Chemical Entities (NCEs), and furthermore all the observed differences between the pre- and post-1963 NCE flows could be attributed to the 1962 Amendments. A study done by Steward (1977) of the new pharmaceutical products and new chemicals introduced in the US between 1948 and 1975 demonstrated a marked decrease in both quantities during the 19605. However when comparable data for the UK was used, it also indicated a decline in total pharmaceutical products and in new chemical entities beginning about 1960. Thus, it would appear from this evidence that the Kefauver—Harris Amendments were not the only factor in causing a decline in pharmaceutical innovations in the United States, but that the decline was part of a broader, underlying phenomenon which was operating worldwide. Comparison of the US and UK data does show, however, that the rate of decline was very much sharper in the US than in the UK, which might be taken to indicate the added impact in the US of the 1962 Amendments. However, it is not only the quantity of new drugs which is important, but also their quality, that is their therapeutic significance. Using data for the years 1950 to 1973, Steward (1977) examined the annual approval of NCEs by degree of therapeutic 1 Following the thalidomide tragedy, the US Congress passed the Kefauver-Harris Amendments. This extended the mandate and regulatory control of the FDA in several ways: - it required firms to provide documented scientific evidence of a new drug's efficiency in addition to the proof-of-safety required by the original law. - it gave the FDA, for the first time, discretionary power over the clinical research process. Thus, prior to any tests on human beings, firms are now required to submit a new drug investigational plan (IND) giving the results of animal tests and research protocols for human tests. importance modest gait introductiot introductior Ano‘ market laun 19711. The in the L'nit their accep PTOducts 2 9011111116; United Sr 1’.) EJ CODCen [he Ciel [he inc ‘ \' ofiefip. 28 importance2 . It was found that while there was a general downward trend for drugs with modest gain and little or no gain, the 1962 Amendments had little impact on the rate of introduction of drugs offering an important gain. However, a marked decrease in new introductions for all three classes of drugs was found to have occurred between 1966 and 1969. This might represent the true impact of the 1962 Amendments taking into account the lead times inherent in new drug development. Another effect of regulation on innovation of pharmaceuticals is in delaying the market launch of new products and processes through lengthening approval times (Garrett 1974). There is also evidence to suggest that because of the greater severity of regulation in the United States, important new drugs are sometimes marketed there, many years after their acceptance in other countries. For example, in 1989, eighteen of the twenty-three new products approved for marketing in the US had received their first marketing approval in countries other than the US. During 1984-88, 88 of the 113 products introduced in the United States were first approved in a foreign country (PMA Statistical Fact Book 1989). Section 3.2 discusses additional regulatory effects such as patent laws, pricing policies, and product liability laws on pharmaceutical innovation. 3.2 I l'E .1 EN ._ IN HE LAO} ' 5L ‘ TI ,2- 121111518! Empirical analysis of competitiveness in the global pharmaceutical industry has concentrated primarily on factors influencing the supply of ethical pharmaceutical products (factors affecting innovation). Further, much of the analysis is related to or in response to the debate regarding the effects of regulatory measures and other government policies on the industry. For the most part, research has focused on the activities of US firms in the 2 NCEs are classified by the FDA into three categories: (1) drugs offering little or no gain, (2) drugs offering modest gain and (3) drugs with important gains. firms. Gro‘ successful Phannaceuti ill Bus 0an regr 112) Dr, bio 131 A? sul (4} De pl'r phal'l’tlacr R&D int 01 l‘Egu] (L'SlTr phamta eCQTlor Japan. Sales 1: twentt 29 US market. Empirical analysis of the US industry's competitive position in the international market is relatively limited. 3.2.1 i v i Research is the foundation of competitive strength for modern pharmaceutical firms. Growth in sales and profits for major ethical drug companies are derived from successful new products discovered and developed through industry research efforts. Pharmaceutical research may be divided into four phases: (1) Basic research - advancement of basic pharmacological knowledge. This is the only phase not directly regulated by the government, although government regulation has a substantial indirect impact. (2) Discovery effort - the synthesis of active substances and the establishment of biological effect. (3) Applied research - the extensive biological (animal) and clinical (human) testing of substances to determine pharmacological activity and risk of adverse effects. (4) Development - the determination of dosage form, the development of manufacturing processes, and the production of drug product. Since investment in R&D is one of the most important criteria for success in the pharmaceutical industry and since regulation is one of the most common factors affecting R&D investment decisions of firms, most empirical studies have concentrated on the effect of regulation on R&D as mentioned above. Some of these studies are reviewed below. The most recent study to date was done by the US International Trade Commission (USITC 1991). This study was done to assess the competitive position of the US pharmaceutical industry in the global economy. This study used two data sets. The first data set consisted of various annual economic, demographic and health related measures from 1983-88 for seven countries whose pharmaceutical industries are competitive. These were: France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Spain, UK and US. This data set was used to do a country level analysis. The second data set comprised of various measures relating to R&D, firm size and sales for a sample of pharmaceutical firms from US, Western Europe and Japan. A total of twenty-nine firms were used. This data set was used to do a regional comparison at the firm level. of the studs 13) Na . 131 11121 Grat with respect 91 COFporat 1961-8613 World widt- Which the S“ltzerlan Ho for majorr i5 CUrrentl det'elgpm Corrlmerci Hr could pro decfidee pOSlllon l markets are incre 30 firm level. The analysis consisted of a number of regression estimates. The main findings of the study were: (1) A growing national economy provides an important underlying base for the pharmaceutical industry. Growth in national income, growth in GDP/capita, and a higher life expectancy were used as indicators of a growing economy. (2) National research efforts help foster the discovery of innovative NCEs and that relatively higher prices for pharmaceuticals partially explain the larger number of NCEs introduced into a country. (3) Higher levels of R&D expenditures and R&D employees are important for global market share and productivity. Grabowski (1989) examined the competitiveness of the US pharmaceutical industry with respect to indicators such as: (1) number of new products under development in 1986 by corporate nationality (2) new product introductions by corporate nationality during 1961-86 (3) number of global NCEs by nationality of originating firm during 1970-83 (4) world wide sales by corporate nationality for 1980, 1984 and 1986. The countries for which the above data was compared were US, Japan, West Germany, France, Italy, Switzerland and UK. However no statistical tests were conducted. The raw data was simply examined for major trends in order to draw conclusions. Grabowski concluded that the US industry is currently the leader in worldwide sales, R&D activity and new drug candidates under development. The US industry was also found to be significantly more responsible for commercially important new drugs and global N CEs. However Grabowski also cautioned that foreign competitors particularly Japan could provide a strong challenge to US leadership in pharmaceuticals over the next few decades. The European pharmaceutical industries were found to have a generally declining position in the 19805. This was attributed to control on drug prices in their domestic markets. Grabowski also concludes by saying that current US policies in the health sector are increasingly driven by priorities that could result in a less favorable economic environment for new product introductions. The status of th study used . production. foreign nont policies. an. The Significant PerlOmran the industr In Administ imfil‘ttatic C91lid all 1096312 1 CoUllll‘ie SUCCeSS: beSUCCr 31 The National Academy of Engineering conducted a study to evaluate the competitive status of the US pharmaceutical industry in the international market (NAB 1983). The study used six indicators to measure competitiveness: research effort, innovative output, production, sales, market structure and international trade. Data for the US, Western Europe and Japan was compared. The study found a decline in US based drug production as a percentage of world drug production, and a decline in the US share of world pharmaceutical R&D. A combination of factors were blamed for the decline. These were: foreign nontariff barriers, US FDA regulations, patent laws, product liability laws, antitrust policies, and R&D tax incentives. The NAE study concluded that although the US industry was likely to remain a significant force in the international market, decreases in various measures of industrial performance relative to other major international pharmaceutical producers suggested that the industry would lose its dominant position. In a follow up study by the US Department of Commerce's International Trade Administration (ITA 1984), it was concluded that US was and would continue to be internationally competitive. However the study identified a number of policy issues that could affect the global position of the industry. It concluded that US companies were likely to be at a disadvantage because of the significantly longer US regulatory review periods. Thomas (1989) compared the performance of the US industry to that of other countries' industries using a ten nation sample. He concluded that firms competing successfully in the international market do so by developing innovative new drugs that can be successfully marketed in most major country markets. He suggested that a critical factor contributing to a company's ability to compete successfully in the international market is the degree of competition in the company's home market. Three factors contribute to competitive home country markets: rigorous quality restrictions on market access; high levels of publicly funded biomedical research; and unregulated domestic prices. Aft such as sci. important it _. issues in the influence th Hos Commissic 01 new pl innovation COutpetitit Ofpharmt elarttirte innoyatio A Cmcia] fl prDPOSitj indugtqu C Pharmak. PaTkEr'g imemati 32 A report issued by the Council on Competitiveness (1991) emphasizes that factors such as science education, funding for R&D, and relative freedom from price control are important to the continued competitiveness of the US industry. Table 3.1 presents an overview of the studies on global pharmaceutical competitiveness. 3.2.2 WWW As mentioned earlier, most conceptual and empirical work on competitiveness issues in the pharmaceutical industry has concentrated on supply factors, i.e., factors that influence the extent and rate of pharmaceutical innovation. However as recently pointed out in the report by the US International Trade Commission, it is equally important to look at factors that affect the inter-country diffusion of new pharmaceutical products, i.e., factors affecting demand for pharmaceutical innovations across national markets. Knowledge of such factors provides the firm with a competitive advantage with respect to choosing markets more strategically for introduction of pharmaceutical innovations. It is also important from a public policy perspective to examine factors that delay market introduction of therapeutically significant drug innovations. According to Redwood (1988), the ability to both innovate and market new drugs is crucial for global competitiveness and that "one without the other is hardly a tenable proposition for survival in the upper reaches of the ethical sector of the pharmaceutical industry" (p. 72). Only a handful of empirical studies have examined the factors affecting diffusion of pharmaceutical innovations in the international context. The few, with the exception of Parker's study (Parker 1984), have focused on the effect of regulatory conditions on the international diffusion of new drugs. NAE119§3 lTA llgfx‘: momas 33 Table 3.1: Overview of Studies on Global Pharmaceutical Competitiveness Study (a) Factors examined Determinants of (b) Countries/Regions Competitiveness (findings) USITC (1991) (a) Economic, demographic and Innovation; growing economy, social factors; R&D measures; R&D incentives; low price firm size; and sales. control; R&D investment. (b) France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Spain, UK, and US. Grabowski (1989) (a) Number of drugs under Innovation; R&D investment; development; NCE introductions; commercial potential of NCE. global NCEs developed; global sales. (b) US, Japan, Germany, France, Italy, Switzerland, and UK. NAE ( 1983) (a) Research investment; regulatory conditions - innovative output; production; specifically FDA regulations; sales; market structure and trade patent laws; product liability balance. laws; antitrust policies; and R&D (b) US, Japan and Western tax incentives. Europe. ITA (1984) (a) Sales; production; Innovation; productivity of R&D; employment; productivity; R&D; regulatory approval time; quality and profitability data. of NCE. (b) Industrialized countries. Thomas (1989) (a) Various regulatory and market Innovation; competitive markets; Council on Competitiveness (1991) related factors (b) Industrialized countries (a) Various regulatory and economic factors. (b) Industrialized countries. stringent quality regulations; high research funding; and unregulated domestic prices. Science education; R&D funding; and freedom from price control. . _ . 1...... 2 :11... e 34 Grabowski and Vernon (1977) analyzed the introduction of US discovered drugs into the UK for 1960—1972, to see the effect of the Kefauver-Harris Amendment on US firms' strategy on foreign NCE introductions. A dramatic shift was found to have occurred as a result of the Amendment. For the early 19605, US firms introduced majority of the new drugs into UK orgy after first introducing them into the US. For the period 1972- 1974, however, more than two-thirds of US discovered NCEs were first introduced into the UK instead of the US. Grabowski (1980) found a lag in foreign discovered NCE introductions into the US with respect to Europe. More seriously, the lag with Europe was not confined to drugs with little or modest therapeutic gain, but also included drugs that the FDA itself ranked as significant therapeutic advances. He attributed regulatory changes as the major factor contributing to the lag. Lag of foreign discovered NCEs was especially significant because foreign discovered NCEs accounted for one half of the drugs rated therapeutically significant by the FDA during the period analyzed (1968-1973). These medically significant drugs of foreign origin were all introduced into the US with very long time lags - three to six years after they were introduced into the UK Popper and Nason (1993) examined the effect of various regulatory conditions using NCE introduction data over a twenty year period, 1970-1989. The countries for which the data was collected were France, Germany, UK, Italy, Japan and the US. The regulatory aspects that were examined for their effect on extent and tinting of NCE introductions were: generic substitution, national health insurance plans, national formulary system, acceptance of foreign clinical testing, patent protection, compulsory out-licensing and R&D pricing incentives. Both generic substitution policies and presence of national health plans seemed to increase diffusion lags. Compulsory out-licensing did not seem to affect number of product introductions but significantly increased the time taken for products to reach the market. Acceptance of foreign clinical data was associated with shorter time lag to 35 introduction as were R&D pricing incentives. Market size was found to be positively related to number of product introductions but did not influence time lag for introduction. The most comprehensive study to date on international diffusion of pharmaceuticals is the study by Parker (1984). Parker used a sample of eighteen countries comprising of nine industrialized and nine developing countries. The time frame used in the study was from 1954 to 1978. A total of 192 brand name pharmaceuticals were included in the analysis. The arrival time lag or diffusion lag was the dependent variable. This was measured as the time between marketing of the drug for the first time in a country and its subsequent marketing elsewhere. The independent variables examined were: regulatory tightness of country, therapeutic importance of drug, market attractiveness, and type of country. Countries with the toughest regulatory environments had the lowest mean arrival time lags. Parker attributed this surprising result to the relationship between market size and regulatory environment. The countries with the stringent regulatory environments were also the ones with the large market size. Therefore countries with a larger market size seemed to attract products earlier than those with a smaller market size inspite of the regulatory climate. Mean arrival time lags were shorter for more important drugs than for less important drugs but the relationship was not significant. With respect to type of country, drug introductions were fewer among the less developed economics as well as having higher mean arrival time lags. Table 3.2 presents an overview of the studies on global pharmaceutical diffusion. 3.2.3 ___._. 2H. _|'r_:na F 11. i Pr: m' il in' ..V‘_!T_ Figure 3.1 illustrates the various supply and demand factors affecting competitiveness in the global pharmaceutical industry. As shown in the figure, the demand for ethical pharmaceuticals is determined by demographic and socioeconomic factors, such as age of the population, diet or access to health care, etc. Government policies and 36 Table 3.2: Overview of Studies on Global Pharmaceutical Diffusion Study (a) Factors examined Findings (b)Countries/Re£ions Grabowski and Vernon (a) Regulatory approval Diffusion lag in the US due (1977) time. to longer approval times. (b) US and UK. Grabowski (1980) (a) Regulatory approval Diffusion lag in the US due time; and therapeutic to longer approval time. importance of NCE. (b) US and Europe. Popper and Nason ( 1994) (a) Regulatory aspects; and Regulatory aspects affect Market size. rate and extent of diffusion. (b) France, Germany, UK, Italy, Japan, and US. Parker (1984) (a) Regulation; therapeutic Regulation and market size importance of NCE; market interact to affect diffusion; size; and type of country. (b) Nine industrialized and nine developing countries. diffusion is faster for more important NCEs; and developing countries have longer diffusion lags. 37 programs such as cost-containment, degree of health-care financing, and support for health-related education may also affect the demand for drugs, directly or indirectly. An important factor affecting the supply of ethical pharmaceuticals is R&D activity, i.e., the level and productivity of R&D spending. Such activity requires sufficiently high profits, the ability to secure external financing, or both. Government actions ranging from macroeconomic policies, treatment of product liability, tax policy, and regulatory controls exert indirect and direct effects (positive and negative) on the ability of firms and the industry as a whole to produce pharmaceuticals. The demographic, social, economic, political, legal, and market related characteristics that affect the international supply and demand for pharmaceutical innovations are discussed below. 3.2.3.1 i Envir nm 11 om i ' National differences in population, density, life expectancy, birth rate, death rate, composition, distribution, etc., create variations in market conditions which offer opportunities as well as threats. They also influence supply and demand. Larger the market potential for pharmaceuticals in a particular country, greater will be the incentive for the firms in that country to innovate and introduce new products. A key demographic factor affecting market potential for ethical pharmaceuticals is the proportion of the elderly populace. Projections show that the population in many industrialized countries is aging quickly. The frequency of drug consumption is rising most rapidly in markets where the population is aging. For example, data for Germany show that roughly 55 per cent of the population aged over 44 years takes drugs at least once a week but only 15 per cent of those between 14 and 44 years of age consume drugs this frequently (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). Moreover, the types of drugs required by individuals aged under 45 years are different from those purchased by the elderly. They consist mainly of pain- 38 Figure 3.1: Determinants of Global Market Share in the Pharmaceutical Industry r1 Global flaunt Shore mm 2mm 2mm Source: USITC (1991) 39 killers, cough and cold preparations and digestives. These are frequently generics and are less expensive than other drug types. One-sixth of all Germans will be over 65 by the year 2000 and by 2010 half the country's population will be 50 years or older. In contrast, in a developing country like India only 25 per cent of the population will be fifty years or older by 2010 (Redwood 1988). 3.2.3.2 Soeial Eovironment god Commtitiveoess These include the health care systems of the country - private and public, dispensing practices of physicians, nature of consumer demand for pharmaceuticals, etc. The types of national health care systems in industrialized and developing countries differ greatly and their effects on the pattern of pharmaceutical consumption are equally disparate. Governments in industrialized countries established very generous systems of health care in periods when national income was rising and the proportion of old people in the population was comparatively small. The public sector in most industrialized countries accounts for more than half of all drug expenditures. The only exceptions are Canada and the United States; in both countries a large portion of pharmaceutical expenditures is covered by private medical insurance or involves direct payments by patients (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). Systems of public health care are a less significant determinant of consumption in the developing countries. The main reason is the small proportion of total income available for this purpose. Public expenditures on health care in most developing countries account for between one and two per cent of gross national product (GNP), while in the industrialized countries the figure is much higher, typically between six and eight per cent. As much as two-thirds of the drugs purchased by patients in poor and medium-income developing countries are paid for privately (Redwood 1987, p. 254-6). 40 Both the supply and demand for pharmaceutical innovations will be affected by the nature of the public health systems. Greater the public health expenditure in a country, greater will be the demand (hence diffusion) of new drugs as well as greater will be the investments in the innovation process to generate N CEs due to the larger size of the market. Several industrialized countries are now being forced to cut back on their health care programs and pharmaceuticals are a favorite target. Reasons for the cutbacks include the rising costs of caring for an aging population, the introduction of new and more expensive drugs, and a general tightening of federal budgets. Because a large portion of the total spending on drugs is paid for through public funds, the change in policy is having a dramatic effect on consumption. The steps taken by policy makers include the introduction of stricter policy controls, the withdrawal of reimbursements from selected products and increases in patient contributions to the cost of drugs. Doctors in several industrialized countries are now coming under pressure to prescribe more economically and to use generic substitutes. This tactic is most popular in the US where generics accounted for 29 per cent of all the country's drug sales in 1988. The same is not the case in Western Europe. The slow rate of acceptance is partly due to opposition from industry representatives and from the medical profession. Both groups have vigorously resisted legislation to promote generic substitution. 3.2.3.3 WW These include the overall level of development of the originating countries, per capita income and distribution, disposable income, expenditure patterns, etc. The pharmaceutical industry is highly research oriented and development of new ethical pharmaceuticals runs into millions of dollars. Developed country firms based in a growing or robust economy are the only ones which can afford such costly investment. For example, Western European and American 41 dnrg companies have accounted for nearly 80 per cent of all NMEs (new molecular entities) launched during 1961-90 (USITC 1991). The economic attractiveness of markets is likely to be a significant influence on the rate of inter-country spread of drugs. Wealthy countries with large markets for pharmaceuticals may exert a strong commercial pull and attract foreign developed drugs earlier than other poorer nations with less purchasing power. For example, the US pharmaceutical industry has invested extensively throughout the world. However, investment by the US pharmaceutical industry in the developed nations accounted for about 75 percent of the total investment in 1986, with developing countries accounting for only 25 percent. The major markets for US. drug exports in 1989 were Japan (21 percent of total), Germany (10 percent), Canada (8 percent) and Italy (6 percent). The top seven pharmaceutical markets in the world accounted for 77 percent of the world pharmaceutical sales in 1989. These countries were France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Spain, the United Kingdom, and the United States. Thus the extent of diffusion is clearly affected by market attractiveness (U .S. Department of Commerce, 1989). More than 70 per cent of all pharmaceuticals are sold in developed market economies. The developing countries account for less than a fifth, with the remainder being consumed in East European countries and the USSR (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992, Figure 3.2). Japan reports the largest share of per capita income spent on pharmaceuticals (1.62 per cent in 1990) - almost twice the level in North America and some parts of Western Europe. No similar increases have occurred in developing countries. In fact the share of per capita gross domestic product (GDP) spent on pharmaceuticals has actually declined in many of the poorer countries. 3.2.3.4 i’ vir t n iiv s Factors such as political stability and continuity, ideological orientation, government involvement in business, attitudes towards MNCs, national economic and 42 developmental priorities, etc., will affect a firm's ability and propensity to invest in R&D and thus supply of innovative pharmaceutical products (Thorelli 1990; Toyne and Walters 1993). The industrialized countries are the most stable politically and emphasize basic Figure 3.2: World Consumption of Pharmaceuticals, 1992 Eastern Europe 9.3% Developing economies 18.9% Developed Economies 71 .7°/o research priorities. Firms from such countries are therefore likely to invest heavily in R&D and produce more new chemical entities. Political factors will also affect a firm's decision to introduce a new product in a particular country (Thorelli 1990; Toyne and Walters 1993). Greater the number of destination countries with high political instability, high government involvement in business, high hostility of the government toward foreign firms or MNCs, and/or differing ideologies of the governments, lower will be the extent and rate of global diffusion of the product. For example, the pharmaceutical market share held by domestic firms in the former Soviet Union in 1985 was a 100 percent with zero percent foreign involvement. In comparison, market share by domestic firms in Canada was only 18 percent in 1985, reflecting the high investment by foreign firms in Canada (Pradhan 1983, p. 21). 43 3.2.3.5 Envir en ' 'v Government policies whether domestic or international can have a significant impact both on the rate and extent of innovation in a country's industry as well as rate and extent of diffusion of NCEs into the country, given the nature of the industry. These government policies include regulatory approval procedures, pricing policies, cost-containment efforts, patent law and intellectual property rights, product liability laws, and tariff related matters such as granting of duty suspensions. Figure 3.3 illustrates the entire drug development process cycle starting from basic research to its market approval to patent expiry and finally re-investment in the research process. As seen in the figure, much of the area of maximum risk is also that of maximum intervention by regulatory authorities, reaching a financial climax when it comes to pricing and social security reimbursement. As has been described in the previous sections, the role of regulation, in particular the effect of changes in the US regulatory procedure for market approval of N CEs has been the subject of analysis in majority of the studies on pharmaceutical innovation and diffusion. The empirical studies examining this issue have been discussed above, thus the section below will only focus on the regulatory approval procedures of other countries in comparison to the US. Also other aspects of regulation mentioned above that affect the supply and demand for innovation are discussed below: Regulatory approval for new drugs: varies by country. Generally under the FDCA, a new drug may not be commercially marketed in the United States, unless it has been approved as safe and effective by the FDA. The average FDA review time for the 20 new drugs approved in the United States in 1988 was about 31 months, compared with an average of approximately 15 months for foreign review of those of the 20 products that were first approved overseas (PMA 1989). The drug development process from discovery to FDA approval takes approximately 10 years. Any delays in the development and 44 Figure 3.3 Risks in Pharmaceutical R&D Screenin /—\. , Discovery, Fiei vestment Patent protection P fit \ IDEVELOPMENT I Area of Maximum ”"3““ clinical Post-marketing 913“ trials,etc surveillance Registration International Marketing \ Pricing Lauk / Maximum intervention by A h .. \Fieimbursement ut ontres Adapted from Redwood (1991) 45 marketing approval process shorten's a product's effective patent life, reducing the period in which a company can recoup its R&D expenditures. Regulatory approval procedures of different countries affect perceived market attractiveness and thus affect the decision of a firm with respect to the choice of country for first launch of a new product. Industry sources state that a perceived differential in approval times prompts many companies to seek market approvals overseas first. For example, in 1989, 18 of the 23 products approved in the United States had received their first marketing approval in countries other than the United States. During 1984—88, 88 of the 113 products introduced in the United States were first approved in a foreign country (PMA 1989). Drug approval regulations in Japan also inhibit diffusion of drugs into that country. Foreign firms in Japan were prohibited from applying on their own for the first step of drug approval, i.e., the demonstration of efficacy and safety review, and clinical trials had to be conducted in Japan on native citizens. Both policies remained in effect until the mid- 19805, when discussions with the United States in bilateral trade negotiations resulted in changes that allowed foreign firms to apply directly and permitted the submission of the results of foreign clinical trials. However incompatibility of the data is still an issue in many areas. Some human clinical studies must still be performed in Japan, to Japanese standards, resulting in duplication of efforts for foreign firms (Medical Marketing 1990). Efforts have been made for international harmonization of approval procedures in the recent years. In 1991, the International Conference on the Harmonization of Technical Requirements for Registration of Pharmaceuticals was held in Brussels. The objective of the conference was to look at harmonizing current approaches to drug regulation and minimizing future divergence of new registration requirements (Scrip Review 1991). Patent Law and Protection of Intellectual Property Rights: Patents are the most important of the statutorily created forms of intellectual property for the pharmaceutical 46 industry. According to one source, losses from patent, copyright and trademark infringement were estimated to cost the industry $ 6 billion in 1986 resulting in a decrease of S 720-900 million in R&D spending (Merck & Co. 1988). Types of protection vary widely between nations. The average time taken to grant a patent also varies by country. The average time it takes for the Japanese Patent Office to grant a patent is about 5 years from date of filing compared to about 20 months in the United States (The Japan Times, 1990). Firms in industrialized countries which have stringent patent protection laws will have more incentive to invest in research and thus will be more productive in discovering NCEs and other new pharmaceutical products. According to the Pharmaceutical Manufacturer's Association (PMA), "hostile governments, lack of patent protection and well-entrenched patent pirates are reducing the market share and presence of US. pharmaceutical companies" in countries such as Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, and Peru (PMA 1990, p.22). Developing countries in general offer poor patent protection thus discouraging the diffusion of new drugs into the country. Pricing and Cost-containment Policies: Pricing is considered to be one of the "main determinants of margins, research capacities, and internationalization" (European Chemical News, 1989, p. 20). Pricing policies of different countries vary depending on national objectives and affect the market attractiveness of a nation and hence the rate and extent of pharmaceutical innovation and diffusion. The United States, for example, has to date not implemented price controls on pharmaceuticals and is considered by many to be the country with the "last of the free pricing" (USITC 1991, pp. 3-19). Pricing controls on pharmaceutical products marketed in the EC are implemented by almost all of the member states. According to Redwood (1991), the national pharmaceutical industries of countries with low prices have gradually become less competitive internationally, both as originators of genuinely innovative drugs and in their penetration of international markets. A study by 47 Barral (1987), demonstrated that the research output of national pharmaceutical industries lines up more or less inversely to the severity of their drug pricing and reimbursement systems. Redwood (1991) also found a pattern between pricing freedom and trade balance. Of the countries with pricing freedom, only the Netherlands had a trade deficit, whereas no country with product by product price control had a pharmaceutical trade surplus. The effect of price control was expressed by Redwood in medical language as follows: "Drug price control is contra-indicated for high-risk and innovative R&D. Adverse reactions include a propensity to concentrate on the domestic market and to abstain from multinational investment. The result is competitive anemia, one symptom of which is a negative trade balance. The disease is chronic rather than acute, and it cannot be cured overnight. Long-term control breeds long-term debility" (p. 25). Figure 3.4 illustrates the differential effects of the types of pricing systems (free versus controlled) on pharmaceutical R&D and the political agencies. According to the figure, the interaction of pricing and R&D is not an instant relationship, but one that works its way through the system over the years as a kind of slow motion spiral, for whose twists management and the authorities can be responsible at different times. Cost containment programs have been implemented by a number of countries such as EC member states, and Japan for health care expenditures. Among other things, these programs are intended to lower the portion of health-care expenditures accounted for by pharmaceuticals. The implementation of such programs is becoming more prevalent worldwide as national health-care expenditures continue to increase in many countries. Levels of R&D spending in the pharmaceutical industry have been found to decline as a result of price controls and/or cost-containment programs on a national level. Reduced level of R&D spending also leads to reduced innovativeness. Most developing countries place price controls on pharmaceuticals reducing perceived market potential and thus diffusion of new products into their markets. This results from the fact that medicines are a "basic need." Drugs account for as much as half Of all health care expenditures in these countries (compared to 8-10 percent in industrialized 48 Figure 3.4 Pricing Systems and Effects on R&D [ PRICING SYSTEM [minnows—5| Profits High Low Risk Strong Weak 0 High, Rising Lower, rising R&D Success Rare Very rare NCE Price Very high As high as permitted Re-invest R&D Very high As high as possible Next NCE Price ‘ Still higher As high as permitted P Iitical reiction —> More pressure More control Source: Redwood (1991) 49 countries). Any increase in prices is extremely costly in terms of the health benefits forgone. Policy makers therefore apply tight price controls, sometimes imposing price freezes for extended periods of time (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). Such measures can reduce market attractiveness and thus the supply and demand for pharmaceutical innovations. Product Liability : Product liability law deals with the right of a consumer to sue the manufacturer of a product for injuries caused by a perceived defect in the product. Some countries permit a manufacturer to defend against a product liability suit on the ground that a governmental authority such as the FDA has tested and approved the product as safe. US. courts generally do not recognize such a defense and producers face potentially enormous liability even after the government has declared the product to be essentially free of defects (USITC 1991, p. 3-27). Innovation in the US. industry is stunted by concern over potential liability because juries are more likely to find a new product defective than an old, familiar one (Huber 1988). According to some sources, the specter of product liability exposure has led pharmaceutical companies to shy away from research, particularly into areas such as obstetrics and birth control (Council on Competitiveness 1991; Swazey 1991; Lasagna 1991). Also US pharmaceutical companies are finding it more attractive to make their products outside the US to escape US liability law, thus affecting supply of new therapies in the US. Similarly, the diffusion of drugs into the US. from other countries is adversely affected due to stringent product liability measures. R&D Incentives: All the major pharmaceutical producer countries provide at least some government support for pharmaceutical R&D through funding of basic medical research. Federal government support for medical research in the US continues to exceed funds 50 allocated by other national governments. Developing countries can hardly afford such largesse. 3.2.3.6 k tr t ti ivene Market and/or industry structure can affect both supply and demand of innovative pharmaceuticals. Factors such level of competition in national as well as international markets, level of diversification in the industry, industry growth, etc., can have an effect on the supply and diffusion of new drugs. When the pharmaceutical industry is pictured in global terms, a handful of multinationals are found to dominate. A high degree of concentration prevails in international markets. The top 25 companies in the world account for 44 per cent of the world market. Fourteen of these companies are based in the United States (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). Most multinationals are also engaged in a range of activities other than pharmaceuticals. In fact most of the world's largest drug companies obtain the bulk of their revenue from the sale of non-pharmaceutical products. For example, Hoechst, Ciba— Geigy, Bayer and Rhone-Poulenc are primarily chemical firms with large pharmaceutical departments. Diversification of this type is sometimes regarded as a strategic advantage. That may be true in the sense that the very size of the company offers a degree of financial support which specialized competitors do not enjoy. However the fact that Merck, Glaxo and a number of other multinationals depend on pharmaceuticals for more than two-thirds of their total revenue suggests that this advantage, if it exists, is far from decisive (Financial World 1989). The world's leading pharmaceutical companies are a select group. Entry into this club is very difficult, requiring large teams of researchers as well as a marketing network capable of distributing products on an international or even a global scale. 51 Product competition in individual markets is not always vigorous. This is because some markets are dominated by a few, relatively efficient drugs which are patent-protected. In other instances the patents of the leading brands have expired but the products continue to be leader due to brand loyalty. Large pharmaceutical firms spend huge sums on product promotion of brand name drugs, which is clearly a mechanism by which returns to innovation are realized. Some analysts suggest that brand-name loyalty may be a more effective method of guaranteeing high returns than the patent system itself (Lall 1985). Demand can also be affected by factors such as the pharmaceutical distribution systems in the country. For example, Japan has a complex wholesale pharmaceutical distribution system and is considered a barrier by several foreign firms. An additional factor that affects market demand (market potential) in Japan is that Japanese physicians both prescribe and dispense medications, gaining income from the difference between their dispensing price and the official reimbursement price. To reach these 180,000 physicians, foreign pharmaceutical firms must supplement their own sales forces with wholesalers' detailrnen. However, the above system indirectly increases the market for pharmaceuticals for firms in Japan, since it provides an incentive to physicians in Japan to prescribe more medications (USITC 1991). The degree of market power and the extent of competition do not seem to differ significantly between the industrialized and developing countries. A few companies are world leaders and occupy prominent positions in the markets of both country groups. Nevertheless the implications for policy makers and consumers in developing countries are worrying. The domestic industry in these countries is relatively weak and consists exclusively of small firms which can pose no challenge to the multinationals. This can mean that markets are relatively vulnerable to the possible abuse of market power (Redwood 1988). 3.2.3.8 T belongs . chemical category derelnpnx leading 1h ofwofldu Th the new cl nations. 1 have 3 hr Specific t lmIOduce F were thi infectivi 1991, p indust minke the ja 52 3.2.3.8 n v ' n i l f r o i iven ss The market potential of the therapeutic category to which the new chemical entity belongs will affect the level of R&D investment and consequently the number of new chemical entities introduced in a given time period. For example, the leading therapeutic category in terms of R&D investment in 1989 was anti-infectives with 1,215 products in development worldwide. Neurologicals, anti-cancer, and cardiovasculars were the other leading therapeutic categories. These were also the categories that topped the list in terms of worldwide revenue (Scrip 1990). Therapeutic category of innovation would also determine the nature of demand for the new chemical entity. Disease patterns may vary widely between temperate and tropical nations. Some drugs will have general clinical relevance across all nations. Others will have a limited market because they treat medical conditions which are relatively rare and specific to particular countries. The drugs that have a universal relevance are likely to be introduced into many nations. For example, in 1989, cardiovascular and central nervous system (CNS) products were the two leading categories of ethical drugs in terms of US. sales whereas anti- infective and cardiovascular products were the two leading categories overseas (USITC 1991, p. 1-2). Table 3.3 lists the environmental conditions and factors that affect global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. 3.2.4 v ° n r ti iv n I s As discussed above, international competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry depends on a complex interaction of demographic, economic, social, cultural, market and legal characteristics. The many hurdles, delays and problems encountered by the Japanese in countering competition from the traditionally dominating American and 53 Table 3.3: Environmental Conditions and Global Pharmaceutical Competitiveness Environment Factors (1) Demographic Environment (2) Social Environment (3) Economic Environment (4) Political Environment (5) Legal Environment (6) Market/Industry Environment (7) Innovation Specific Factors Population, density, life expectancy, birth rate, composition/distribution of population, etc. Health care systems, nature of consumer demand, dispensing practices of physicians, etc. GNP/capita, percapita income, expenditure patterns on health care, etc. Government involvement in business, developmental priorities, ideological orientation, etc. Regulatory approval times, patent laws, pricing policies, product liability, R&D tax laws, etc. Market concentration, industry focus, industry growth market size, distribution systems, etc. Demand for therapeutic category. 54 Western European multinationals are instructive when attention turns to developing countries. If Japan, a country with a huge domestic market, ample financial resources and abundant technical skills, requires such a long time to build up a competitive pharmaceutical industry, what are the strategic options available to firms in developing countries? The choices are comparatively few, primarily because producers in developing countries lack research expertise. China seems to be one exception. The country's growing links with firms in industrialized countries reflect the latter's interest in developing retail and OTC products from traditional Chinese herbal remedies. Some foreign participants hope to make use of Chinese research on biological agents which they would convert into drugs. Few firms in developing countries have such a research option. Only a handful have actually discovered an NCE and the instances of collaboration between pairs to firms that are owned and operated from developing countries are few. A multinational usually initiates such contacts; the objective is invariably to gain market access. The multinationals' early moves into developing countries allowed little or no role for local industry. The growth of domestic demand and the lure of larger public-health budgets has made the markets of at least a few developing countries more attractive investment sites. That is the case in several Asian countries where demand for medicines is growing by more than 10 percent each year (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). Many developing countries such as India recognize patents only for processes. Some of the companies in India specialize in developing new chemical processes yielding drugs that are identical to those produced (at much greater expense) by multinationals. The Indian firms begin by selling their new products domestically; later they scale up operations to cut manufacturing costs. The foreign markets which they select as targets are countries that recognize process patents but not patents on the product itself. By the time the companies are ready to export 55 they can often sell the drugs at less than a tenth the price charged by competitors in industrialized countries. This is one of the few means by which developing countries can compete against multinationals. However, the growth of generic markets and the many drugs which will soon come off patent mean that a greater portion of the world's markets could soon be open to producers in developing countries. The Southeast Asian market is also increasing in its importance both as a competitor with respect to new multinationals from Southeast Asia as well as a potential investment area for American, Japanese and European firms. According to Howe (1992), "to be globally competitive into the twenty-first century, pharmaceutical companies will have to be successful in the Southeast Asian market" (p.8). The Southeast Asian region represents the fourth largest market for pharmaceuticals and the fastest growing in the world (Howe 1992). The market tripled in size between 1989 and 1991 and expanded as a base for production as well as sales. The region, together with China, currently consumes approximately eight percent of the world's pharmaceuticals and accounts for over five percent of US pharmaceutical exports (Table 3.4). Of the Southeast Asian countries likely to emerge as powerful competitors in the future, are South Korea, Indonesia, Taiwan and China. Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan, for example, have explicitly named biotechnology as a high priority. To foster development, these countries have created technology centers, offered tax incentives, and tried to improve basic research in order to develop more competent scientists. 3.2.5 it of l b l P rma ti 1 om titive e As shown in Figure 3.5, the model uses the supply and demand framework shown earlier (figure 3.1). The two components of the conceptual framework are: (a) Originating country and industry factors (Supply factors), (b) Destination country factors (Demand factors). 56 Table 3.4: Asian Pharmaceutical Markets by Size Market Size (in US S millions, rounded) Total world $350,000 Japan $33,000 (27.5% of world) Southeast Asia China 4,200 South Korea 2,448 Taiwan 852 Philippines 589 Indonesia 536 Thailand 478 Hong Kong 154 Malaysia 146 Singapore 73 Total Southeast Asia $9,500 (7.9% of world) Source: The [MS Drug Market Manual (Asia), 1990 57 Figure 3.5: Conceptual Model of Global Pharmaceutical Competitiveness Originating country factors Global Innovation & Diffusion Destination country factors SUPPLY DEMAND 3.3 RA I E IV Strategic management of the global supply and demand factors discussed above that affect pharmaceutical sales is crucially important for multinational managers for sustained international competitive advantage. Some of the strategies that were identified in the literature and are applicable to the pharmaceutical industry are discussed below. 3.3.1 Musings: According to Prahalad and Hamel (1990), the most powerful way to prevail in global competition in the 19905 will depend on the ability to exploit core competencies. Core competencies are "the collective learning in the organization, especially the coordination of diverse production skills and integration of multiple streams of technology" (p. 82). Three important characteristics of a core competence in a corporation are: (1) a core competence provides potential access to a wide variety of markets, (2) a core competence should make a significant contribution to the perceived customer benefits of the end product 58 (3) a core competence should be difficult for competitors to imitate. Also core competencies are built through a process of continuous improvement and enhancement that may span a decade or longer. Bogner and Thomas (1992) studied the core competencies in the pharmaceutical industry using a sample of nine firms for intensive case study. They identified two types of competencies in the pharmaceutical industry, namely: (1) competencies in R&D and (2) competencies in marketing and promotion which include ability to handle regulatory requirements. Further they found that the environment in the above areas is constantly changing and that not all firms pick up on these changes. Additionally, firm specific learning with respect to technology and marketing is critical for long term maintenance of competitive advantage. With respect to core competencies in R&D in the pharmaceutical industry, the technological areas that successful firms exploited for discovering new drugs, since the 18705 to the present have been in organic chemistry, fermentation and soilscreening (19405), rational drug design (19705) and biotechnology (19805). Competencies in marketing and promotion have changed from direct selling to physicians (19505) to blockbuster marketing (19805), to specialized selling and handling of regulatory requirements. A second concept made popular by Kogut (1985) and one which particularly applies to this research study, in international strategic management is the concept of comparative advantage-based competitive advantage. It implies the design of international strategies based on the interplay between the comparative advantages of countries and the competitive advantages of fn'ms. COl‘.‘ influences t , referred tn= teehnnlogi. the COmp‘dl Several L': R&D faci L'K. l] arise (in: industry to C01“; which added Chain OULpU diffe. regm CQnC COUd 59 Comparative advantage, sometimes referred to as location specific advantage, influences the decision of where to source and market. Competitive advantage, sometimes referred to as firm-specific advantage, influences the decision of what activities and technologies along the value-added chain a firm should concentrate its resources in, i.e., the core competence of the firm. For example, a US based pharmaceutical firm with a core competence in a certain therapeutic area could choose to locate in a country where there is a greater demand for that therapeutic category and where the approval procedure for new drugs is less stringent than that by the US FDA. This would enable the firm to exploit both the comparative advantage of the foreign country as well as its own competitive advantage. Several US companies for example with core competencies in R&D choose to locate their R&D facilities in the UK rather than the US because of the faster approval process in the UK. Differences in comparative advantages of countries with respect to pharmaceuticals arise due to differences in institutional, cultural, economic, legal, political, market and industry environments. These differences result in differing factor costs thus contributing to competitive advantage of firms that are able to take advantage of the lower factor costs. Differences in the firm-specific advantages or core competencies arise depending on which activities along the value-added chain the firm has invested in learning. The value added chain for pharmaceuticals is illustrated in Figure 3.6. By examining the value-added chain it can be determined which activities will be placed in countries where the comparative advantage is most favorable, thus exploiting differences in input markets. According to Ghoshal (1987), the same can be applied to exploiting differences in output markets, i.e., different countries offer different comparative advantages in terms of differences in consumer tastes and preferences, distribution systems, government regulations, etc. It is also important to remember that comparative advantage is a dynamic concept and can change with changes in government policies and economic or social conditions. 60 Figure 3.6: Value-Added Chain for Pharmaceuticals Basic Research \ Clinical Tooting \Drug Approval Bulk Production \ Formulation Marketing Adapted from Kogut (1985) 3.3.3 l intematn in the g 1989‘). .- products situation I capabilit and inte Phamia Pharma 1990. c I990), Costs, Slime: L3R0 2am; gene] i ICCQE [he 1 ‘ Prici CQm 61 3.3.3 mm In recent years, several experts have studied the effectiveness of alliances in international business and found them to be an important weapon of competitive advantage in the global competitive arena (Hamel, D02 and Prahalad 1989; Harrigan 1987; Ohmae 1989). According to Hamel, D02 and Prahalad, "it takes so much money to develop new products and to penetrate new markets that few companies can go it alone in every situation" (p. 133). The accelerating rate of technological change and the broader range of technological capabilities that firms must possess are also reasons for alliances between firms. Domestic and international mergers, joint ventures, and strategic alliances proliferated in the global pharmaceutical industry in the 19805. According to one source, approximately 131 pharmaceutical firms announced acquisitions or strategic alliances in the first six months of 1990, compared with a total of 51 in 1989 and 56 in 1988 (Medical Advertising Newsletter 1990). i/ The reasons are increasing R&D costs, pressure by governments to contain health costs, and longer drug approval procedures in many countries. One example of an early strategic alliance was the 1983 copromotion agreement between Glaxo and Hoffman- LaRoche. Under the agreement, Hoffman-LaRoche marketed Glaxo's antiulcer product Zantac in the US under the Glaxo trade name, for a percentage of the sales revenue generated. The result was beneficial to both companies, with “Glaxo establishing name recognition in the US and Hoffman-LaRoche generating extra revenue to compensate for the 1985 expiration of its patent on Valium. France - dominated by domestic companies and involvement of the government in pricing approval, has lead many overseas companies to forge alliances with French companies. Italy's market is slightly less nationalistic, but the need to develop a close relation pricing t protitie lheretor a Vehicle| l latrines: advanta relatior. COOperg high to 62 relationship with governmental agencies to obtain more timely approval and attractive pricing makes marketing alliances with domestic companies attractive. According to Shan and Hamilton (1991), such international cooperative ventures provide a firm with access to country-specific advantages embedded in its partners. Therefore "from this perspective, international cooperative relationships may be viewed as a vehicle to tap into the comparative advantages of countries" (p. 419). In their study of a sample of domestic and international cooperative relationships of Japanese firms in the biotechnology industry, Shan and Hamilton found country-specific advantage to be a significant variable in explaining differences between cooperative relationships with partners of different countries. They concluded that interfirm cooperation has implications for international competitiveness of both firms and nations in high technology industries. CHAPTER FOUR METHODOLOGY This chapter has four sections. The first section presents the development of the research questions and objectives. The second section discusses the path models that were tested in the study and the constructs, measures and data sources used. The third section consists of the hypotheses proposed for both models. Finally, the fourth section is a discussion of the statistical technique used (EQS) to analyze the models. 4.1 W The specific research objectives for the study were developed after review of the literature, talking to industry experts, and from the responses of an executive survey carried out to determine the factors affecting global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. The broad objective of the study as indicated in the title of the study was to examine the factors affecting global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. The literature review, expert opinions and the executive survey responses revealed that there are two important factors underlying global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. These are: (1) ability to innovate and (2) ability to market innovations worldwide. These observations led to the following two research objectives or questions: (1) Which country factors stimulate or inhibit a nation's pharmaceutical industry to be globally innovative? (2) Which country factors stimulate or inhibit diffusion of pharmaceutical innovations into its markets? 63 4.1.1 MM As mentioned above, a survey of executives working for multinational pharmaceutical companies was carried out to determine the factors that affect global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. A sample of about 45 multinational pharmaceutical companies was chosen from the 1992 Pharmaceutical Marketers Directory. Two executives from each company were selected for answering the survey. One of the executives was the CEO or President of the company and the second executive selected was the Director for Market Research. Therefore a total of ninety surveys were mailed out. The survey was one page and consisted of two open-ended questions (Figure 4.1). There was also a cover letter explaining the nature of the study with an assurance that all replies would be kept confidential. The respondents were also promised a report of the study results if interested. The executives had the option of filling out the one-page questionnaire and simply faxing the sheet back to the number provided on the sheet or mailing it back in an envelope to the address provided on the same sheet. The questionnaire also indicated that handwritten responses were acceptable. The above measures were designed to increase the response rate by making the task as simple as possible for the executives. 4.1.1.1 rv Re It The exective responses obtained served to confirm the observations from the literature regarding factors affecting global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. Some of the responses from the survey are presented below. (1) In your opinion, what factors make a country's pharmaceutical industry globally competitive? Responses: 0 "Innovation - by far and away the single most important factor." - "Resources to competitively access various markets." umnwu.\ (1) 65 Figure 4.1: Executive Survey xii-$5 Global Compaitivm in the Phamceutical Industry " {isS'N‘ (l) hymopinmmchfmmbaoamfiphmnicdindmyglohflyoompdfiw? (2)1nymopirdmwhichmdreimpauntcdtaiaflnrafimmmmmm fordpmarkatsfqimroducingduirproducts? ledwfimncommareacccpmble PleaseFaxRepflestoMs. MadhuAgrawalat(517)-432-1112 MICHIGAN STATE orMailto:DeptofMarkatingandLogi5tics,MSU,Easthsingm48824 UNIVERSITY 66 - "Innovative differentiated products." 0 "the quality and scope of medical research." 0 "ability to disuibute products on a global scale." (2) In your opinion which are the important criteria that a firm must consider when selecting foreign markets for introducing their products? Responses: Market potential; regulatory environment; competition; reimbursement/pricing systems; patent protection; return on investment, etc. 4.2 E P T Path models were developed to test the above research questions. Based on the conceptual model presented in Chapter 3, two models were designed to test the supply (innovation) and the demand (diffusion) factors affecting global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. 4.2.1 The Global Innovation Model (GIM) Figure 4.2a illustrates the GM model. As shown, three major factors are proposed as affecting the extent of investment in innovation by a country's pharmaceutical industry. These factors are: (a) the economic environment, (b) the regulatory environment, and (c) the market/industry structure. The market/industry environment in also directly affected by the country's economic environment. The extent of innovation investment is proposed as affecting both outbound foreign investment by a country's pharmaceutical industry as well as its success in global innovation. Global innovation is also hypothesized as being affected directly by the extent of foreign investment. Global innovation in turn is proposed as directly affecting the global competitiveness of the country's pharmaceutical industry. 67 Figure 4.2a: The Global Innovation Model 500mm“ Foreign Mkt Environment Investment + (outbound) + 4.. _ Innovation + . . ' . . + Regulation investment Innovation + IIIIIII + Mitt/Industry Structure Figure 4.2b: The Global Diffusion Model Economic Foreign Mkt Envrronment lnvestrnent + (inbound) Market + ‘ ' + Global + Regulation ' Potential ' Diffusion ' Innovation Mitt/Industry Structure 68 42-2 WM (GDM) Figure 4.2b illustrates the global diffusion model. As shown, three major factors are proposed as affecting the market potential for pharmaceutical innovations in a country. ’ These factors are: (a) the economic environment, (b) the regulatory environment, and (c) the market/industry structure. The market/industry environment in also directly affected by the country's economic environment. The market potential is proposed as affecting both Lnllqund foreign investment in the country's pharmaceutical industry as well as global diffusion of innovations into the country. Global diffusion is also hypothesized as being affected directly by the extent of inbound pharmaceutical foreign investment. An additional factor hypothesized as affecting global diffusion is global innovation. That is extent of NCE diffusion into a country is directly affected by the extent of innovation by the country. The individual constructs, measures and data sources for both the above models are discussed below. 4.2.3 Constructs. Measures and Data Sources 4.2.3.1 W (a) W - As discussed in Chapter 3, countries on a higher level of economic development are characterized by more innovative pharmaceutical industries compared to countries that are economically less developed. Several indicators are available by which the economic status of a country can be assessed. Two indicators or measures used in this study were: (1) GNP/Capita (GNP): The average Gross National Product per country's population measured in US dollars for the years under study. (2) Population (POP): The average absolute population for the country for the years under study. 69 (b) W: This is one of the most important factors affecting global innovation. Chapter 3 reviews the literature and empirical studies demonstrating the effects of various regulatory mechanisms on innovation in the pharmaceutical industry. This study uses two regulatory measures: (1) Price regulation (PRICEREG): This is the extent of price control exerted on pharmaceuticals by the government of the country. A seven-point scale, where 1 reflects low price control and 7 reflects high price control is used to measure price control. (2) Approval time (APPTIME): This is the time taken by the drug regulatory agencies to approve an application of a new pharmaceutical product or NCE for marketing in the country. This is measured using a seven-point scale, where 1 reflects short approval time and 7 reflects long approval time. The above measures for regulatory environment are subjective measures determined by the researcher. Although objective values for PRICEREG and APPTIME would have been desirable, the unavailability coupled with the unreliability (due to differences in reporting systems of countries) of the existing objective data on the above indicators made it necessary to resort to subjective measures. An abundance of anecdotal and other information was available to facilitate development of the subjective measures for PRICEREG and APPTINIE. (c) Wm: As was discussed in Chapter 3, the structural aspects of the market and industry can significantly affect the country's innovation potential in pharmaceuticals. Four indicators of market and industry structure were used in this study: (1) Market size (MKTSIZE): This was measured as the average annual sales (in US dollars) of pharmaceuticals for the country for the years under study. (2) Industry focus (INDFOCUS): This was measured as the average percentage ratio of pharmaceutical sales to total sales for the country's industry. (3) Industry growth (INDGRWTH): This was measured as the average annual percentage change in pharmaceutical sales for the country's industry. (4) Industry concentration (INDCONC): This was measured as the percentage of total pharmaceutical sales accounted by the top 25 firms in the industry for the country. 70 (d) Wet: This is the investment in R&D activities by a country's industry. It is a significant predictor of innovative success, since greater the investment in innovation greater should be the success with respect to discovery of new products. One indicator was used for the above construct. ( l) R&D Expenditure (R&DEXPD): This was the average annual expenditure (in US dollars) on pharmaceutical research and development by the country's industry. (e) Qeteeene Eeeeign Investment: Internationalization by a country's pharmaceutical industry is a significant indicator of its size and research potential and has been shown to be positively linked to innovation in most high-technology industries. Two indicators were used to measure outbound foreign investment. (1) Absolute foreign investment (FRGINVST): This was the average annual foreign sales (in US dollars) of pharmaceuticals by the country's industry. (2) Foreign Commitment (FRGCOMM): This was the average percentage ratio of foreign pharmaceutical sales to total pharmaceutical (foreign + domestic) sales for the country's pharmaceutical industry. (e) Glebel Ingevation: This construct reflects the success of the country's industry in developing successfully a new pharmaceutical or NCE. This was measured as: (1) Number of NCEs developed (INNOVAT): This was measured as the total number of NCEs developed by a country's industry for the years under study. (0 W: This reflects the market power of the country's industry in the global market. This was measured as: (1) Global Sales (GBLSALES): This was measured as the average annual worldwide pharmaceutical sales (in US dollars) by the country's pharmaceutical industry. Table 4.1a lists the constructs, measures and data sources used in the Global Innovation Model. 71 Table 4.1a: Constructs, Measures and Data Sources: The Global Innovation Model CONSTRUCTS MEASURES SOURCES (l) Macroeconomic (1) GNP per capita (GNP) World Development Reports, UN Environment (2) Regulation (3) Market/Industry Structure (4) Innovation investment (5) Foreign Market Investment (Outbound) (6) Global Innovation (7) Global Competitiveness (2) Population (POP) (1) Price control (PRICEREG) (2) Approval time (APPTIME) (1) Market size (MKTSIZE) (2)1ndustry focus (INDFOCUS) (3) Industry growth (INDGRWTH) (4) Industry concentration (INDCONC) ( l) R&D Expenditure (R&DEXPD) ( 1) Absolute foreign investment (FRGINV ST) (2) Foreign commitment (FRGCOMM) (1) Number of NCEs developed (INN OVAT) (1) Global Sales (GBLSALES) Publication. World Development Reports, UN Publication. Author's estimates, various sources. Author's estimates, various sources. Scrip Review (various issues). Scrip League Tables. Scrip League Tables. Ballance, Pogany and Forstner (1992). Scrip League Tables. Scrip League Tables. Scrip League Tables. Scrip Review (various issues). Scrip League Tables. 72 4.2.3.2 The filehal Diffusion Medel Four constructs used in the GIM model are also used in the diffusion model (see Figure 4.2a & b). The same indicators were also used. Therefore only those constructs and corresponding measures that are different are discussed below: (a) Marlee; Petential: As discussed in Chapter 3, market potential or market attractiveness is a significant determinant of the country's ability to attract companies desirous of introducing NCEs in that country. This was measured as follows: (1) Market potential (MKTPOT): This was measured as the average annual sales (in US dollars) of pharmaceuticals for the country for the years under study. (b) WM: As discussed in the earlier chapter, the extent of pharmaceutical foreign investment in a country will positively affect the number of new pharmaceuticals introduced into the country every year. This construct was measured as: (1) INFRGN: The average annual value of pharmaceutical imports (in US dollars) into the country. (c) Glebel Diffusien: This construct indicates the recipient country's attractiveness as a market for introduction of new pharmaceutical products. This was measured as: (1) DIFF: The total number of NCEs introduced into the country for the years under study. Table 4.1b lists the constructs, measures and data sources used in the Global Innovation Model. 4.2.4 i 11 Tim 1‘ c All data used in this study was obtained from secondary sources since most data used was objective data. These sources were identified after a thorough review of the literature - both academic and trade journals; consultation with industry experts such as pharmaceutical associations such as the Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Association; and 73 Table 4.1b: Constructs, Measures and Data Sources The Global Diffusion Model CONSTRUCTS MEASURES SOURCES (l) Macroeconomic (1) GNP per capita (GNP) World Development Reports, UN Environment (2) Regulation (3) Market/Industry Structure (4) Market Potential (5) Foreign Market Investment (inbound) (6) Global Diffusion (7) Global Innovation (2) Population (POP) (1) Price control (PRICEREG) (2) Approval time (APPTIME) (1) Industry focus (INDFOCUS) (2) Indusuy growth (INDGRWTH) (3) Industry concentration (INDCONC) (1) Market potential (MKTPOT) (1) Foreign imports (INFRGN) (l) # of NCEs introduced (DIFF) (1) # of NCEs developed (INNOVAT) Publication. World Development Reports, UN Publication. Author's estimates, various sources. Author's estimates, various sources. Scrip League Tables. Scrip League Tables. Ballance, Pogany and Forstner (1992). Scrip Review (various issues). World Trade Annual. Scrip Review (various issues). Scrip Review (various issues). 74 talks with pharmaceutical market research firms such as Scrip, IMS, etc. Tables 4.1 a&b lists the data sources used for the measures in each of the models. The total sample size used in the study was twenty-seven countries (Table 4.2). Data from 202 multinationals representing the above countries was aggregated to obtain country level estimates. The time frame over which the data was examined was for a four year period (1990 to 1994). This time frame was considered appropriate as a longer time frame would involve confounding effects due to the dynamic environmental changes taking place in the industry before the 1990 period, and a shorter time frame would be ineffective in measuring effects such as innovation and diffusion which take place over a period of several months. Also, resource constraints with respect to time available to the researcher for collecting and inputting the data in a usable form prevented use of a longer time frame for the study. Table 4.2: Countries in Sample 4.3 W Argentina Japan Australia Korea Belgium Netherlands Canada New Zealand China Norway Denmark Portugal Finland South Africa France Spain Germany Sweden Hungary Switzerland India Turkey Indonesia UK Israel US Italy A total of thirty hypotheses corresponding to thirty different path relationships were proposed for the global innovation model. Since several of the constructs in the global 75 diffusion model were the same as in the innovation model, resulting in similar paths, only seven unique hypotheses (paths) were applicable to the global diffusion model. The hypotheses were developed from a review of the literature and results of previous empirical studies. Table 4.3a and Table 4.3b list the hypothesized paths, their expected significance and direction for the global innovation model and the global diffusion model respectively. The rationale for each of the hypotheses and the actual result is discussed in detail in the next chapter on results. In order to test the above hypotheses a total of 32 program runs were canied out for the global innovation model and 12 program runs for the global diffusion models. The number of program runs reflects the number of measures used and the paths tested. Table 4.4a and Table 4.4b lists the combination of variables used in each run for the global innovation and the global diffusion models respectively. 4.4 T IALME D AL I -E EQS - a structural equation modeling (SEM) software was used for statistical analysis. Structural equation modeling is an extension of several multivariate techniques (such as multiple regression and factor analysis). It provides a straightforward method of dealing with multiple dependence relationships simultaneously while providing statistical efficiency (Hayduk 1987). 4.4.1 i lin E ( 1) understand the role of causal relationships in statistical analysis. (2) represent a series of causal relationships in a path diagram. ( 3) translate a path diagram into a set of equations for estimation. (4) assess overall model fit using goodness-of-fit measures. 76 Table 4.3a: Hypotheses: The Global Innovation Model Paths Expected Direction Expected Significance H1: GNP --> MKTSIZE + significant H2: GNP --> R&DEXPD + significant H3: PRICEREG ---> MKTSIZE - significant H4: PRICEREG —-> R&DEXPD - significant H5: MKTSIZE --—-> R&DEXPD + significant H6: R&DEXPD -—> FRGINVST + significant H7: R&DEXPD -—> INNOVAT + significant H8: FRGINVST --> INNOVAT + significant H9: INNOVAT -—> GBLSALES + significant H10: GNP --—> INDFOCUS + insignificant H11: PRICEREG ---> INDFOCUS - significant H12: INDFOCU S --> R&DEXPD + significant H13: GNP --> INDGRWTH + insignificant H14: PRICEREG ---> INDGRWTH - significant H15: INDGRWTH --——> R&DEXPD + insignificant H16: GNP ---> INDCONC - insignificant H17: PRICEREG ---> INDCONC + insignificant H18: INDCONC ---> R&DEXPD + insignificant H19: POP --—> MKTSIZE + significant H20: POP -—> R&DEXPD + significant H21: APPTIME --—> MKTSIZE - significant H22: APPTIME -—> R&DEXPD - significant H23: POP --> INDFOCU S + significant H24: APPTIME ---—> INDFOCUS - insignificant H25: POP ---> INDGRWTH + insignificant H26: APPTIME ---> INDGRWTH - significant H27: POP —-> INDCONC - insignificant H28: APPTIME --> INDCONC + insignificant H29: R&DEXPD ~—> FRGCOMM + significant H30: FRGCOMM ---> INNOVAT - insignificant Table 4.3b: Hypotheses: The Global Diffusion Model Paths Expected Direction Expected Significance H1 : INDFOCU S ---> MKTPOT + significant H2: INDGRW'I'H -—-> MKTPOT + significant H3: INDCONC --—> MKTPOT - significant H4: MKTPOT ---> INFRGN + significant H5: MKTPOT --> DIFF 4» significant H6: INFRGN ---> DIFF + significant H7: INNOVAT ---> DIFF + significant 77 Table 4.4a: Program runs for the Global Innovation Model (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (1 1) (12) (13) (14) (15) ( 16) (17) (18) (19) (20) (21) (22) (23) (24) (25) (26) (27) (28) (29) (30) (31) (32) v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gb|sales v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsale5 v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gbl5ales v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3antsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frginvst; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktsize; v4q&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6q'nnovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat;v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2wricereg; v3=mktsize; v4q&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3mnktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktsize; v4q&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gbl5ales Table 4.4b: Program runs for Global Diffusion Model ( 1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) ( 10) ( l 1) C 12) v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=indfocus; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=indgrwth; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=indconc; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=indfocus; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=indgrwth; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=indconc; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=indfocus; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=indgrwth; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3m’ndconc; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=indfocus; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=indgrwth; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=indconc; v4=mktpot; v5=infrgn; v6=diff; v7=innovat 78 4.4.2 Stepe in Struetuel Egeetien Medeling The following steps are involved in analyzing a path model using structural equation modeling: (a) Asseseing identifieatien ef the model: Very often during the estimation process, the computer program is likely to "blow up", i,e., produce meaningless or illogical results resulting in what is termed as "identification problems." In simple terms, an identification problem is the inability of the proposed model to generate unique estimates. Usually there are three sources of identification problem which need to be explored and corrected. (1) A large number of estimated coefficients relative to the number of covariances or correlations, indicated by a small number of degrees of freedom, (2) the use of reciprocal effects (two-way causal arrows between two constructs); or (3) failure to fix the scale of a construct. (b) W: Structural Equation Modeling shares three assumptions with the other multivariate methods: independent observations, random sampling of respondents, and the linearity of all relationships. In addition, Structural Equation Modeling is more sensitive to the distributional characteristics of the data, particularly the departure from multivariate normality or a strong kurtosis (skewness) in the data. A lack of multivariate normality is particularly troublesome because it substantially inflates the chi-square statistic and creates upward bias in critical values for determining coefficient significance. The above assumptions will be tested using options available in EQS. Once the assumptions have been satisfied at acceptable levels, the results will be examined for any offending estimates such as negative error variances, large standard errors, etc. Once it is established that the data meets the assumptions and there are no offending estimates, overall model fit will be assessed by examining goodness-of-fit measures. Goodness-of-fit is a measure of the correspondence of the actual or observed input (covariance or correlation) matrix with that predicted from the proposed model. 79 Finally, the statistical significance and direction of the paths will be examined and interpreted in light of the hypothesized causal relationships. (c) ldtet‘preting and Medifyidg the Model: Once the model is deemed acceptable, modifications to the model may have to be made to improve its fit further based on theoretical justification. Modification indices will be examined to improve model fit. 4.4.3 Igdieeet Effects end Ewe-green Adelysis Two additional steps in this analysis will involve examination of significant indirect effects and differences between groups, in this case the two groups used are the industrialized country group (I) and the developing country group (D). Indirect effects are important for interpretation purposes. For example, PRICEREG affects GBLSALES indirectly through R&DEXPD and INNOVAT. EQS is able to decompose the total effect into direct and indirect effects and provide significance estimates for both. A second useful feature using EQS which will be used in this study is the analysis of multiple groups to test for significant differences in parameters between two or more groups of interest. In this case, the sample of twenty-seven countries will be divided into two groups, one group consisting of industrialized countries and the other group consisting of developing countries. This will be done to examine if there are significant differences in the relationships between variables for the two groups and whether the models developed, fit the two groups equally well as indicated by the goodness-of-fit indices. Figures 4.3a and Figure 4.3b illustrate the EQS models and structural equations used in the program for the global innovation and the global diffusion models respectively. 80 Figure 4.3a The EQS Model for Global Innovation Model Equations: V3 = *Vl - *V2 + E3; V4: *V1 - *V2+ *V3 +E4; V5 = *V4 + E5; V6 = *V4 + *V5 + E6; V7 = *V6 + E7; 81 Figure 4.3b The EQS Model for Global Diffusion Model Equations: V3 = *Vl - *V2 + E3; V4 = *Vl - *V2 + *V3 +E4; V5 = *V4 + E5; V6 = *V4 + *V5 + *V7 + E6; CHAPTER FIVE RESULTS This chapter is divided into five sections. First, results from the analysis of the global innovation models are discussed. Second, results of the two-group analysis, i.e., analysis of the differences between the industrialized (I) nations versus the developing (D) nations are discussed. Third, significant indirect effects on innovation and global sales are discussed. Fourth, the results from the global diffusion model are presented. Finally, some conclusive comments are offered. 5 .1 - E T A total of thirty-two path models were run using EQS in order to analyze the factors affecting innovation in the global pharmaceutical industry for the entire sample of industrialized plus developing (I+D) countries. The overall results are illustrated in Figures 5.1 - 5.8. Appendix A contains the tables showing the standardized path coefficients, t- values, standard errors and the fit indices for the thirty-two runs. All of the individual runs of the model showed a good fit with the hypothesized model. The goodness of fit indices varied from 0.998 to 1.000. The chi-square statistic was also indicative of a good fit to the hypothesized model. The results of the individual hypotheses are discussed below. 82 83 5.1.1 __ - f P "'r'q illt it! 'zen r tvatt (see Figure 5.1). H1: GNP---->MKTSIZE It was hypothesized that countries with a higher GNP/capita would have a larger market size for pharmaceuticals. More than seventy percent of all pharmaceuticals are sold in developed market economies. The developing countries account for less than a fifth of the sales, with the remainder being consumed in East European countries and the Soviet republics (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). Spending on pharmaceuticals in the developed market economies has been rising. Average pharmaceutical consumption as per cent of per capita GDP rose from 0.65 in 1975 to 0.95 in 1990. No similar increases have occurred in developing countries. In fact the share of per capita gross domestic product (GDP) spent on pharmaceuticals has actually declined in many of the poorer countries (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). Another factor which affects the market size in the industrialized countries is the demographic characteristics of the population. As the population of a country ages, the need for drugs grows. For the industrialized countries, it is estimated that by the year 2015, over forty percent of the population will be over 45 years old. In comparison, only 25 per cent of the developing countries' population will be over 45 years of age by 2015. Public expenditures on health care in the industrialized countries are also higher as compared to in the developing countries. As the figure illustrates, the relationship between GNP and MKTSIZE was found to be significant and positive as expected. H2: GNP---->R&DEXPD According to the technology gap theory of development (Fagerberg 1987; Posner 1961; Gomulka 1971; Cornwall 1977), there is a close correlation between level of 84 Figure 5.1 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Market size on Innovation Hypothesized model 4. + 4. PRICEREG - m + GBLSALES ' + ——O significant path -~—----#’ insignificant path Result + PRICEREG ' .+ _’ significant path ..._-....._.. 443» insignificant path 85 economic development of a nation (measured as GNP or GDP per capita) and level of technological development measured using R&D statistics. It was therefore hypothesized that countries with a higher GNP/capita would be associated with a more research intensive pharmaceutical industry reflected in terms of dollar expenditures on pharmaceutical research and development by the respective country's industry. For example, for the period 1980-83, one study estimated that the developed country industries accounted for ninety-six percent of global R&D expenditure on pharmaceuticals whereas the rest of world accounted for just four percent of global research expenses (Redwood 1988). The US. pharmaceutical industry's total R&D expenditure was estimated to be $7.3 billion in 1989 (USITC 1991). As the figure illustrates, the relationship between GNP and R&DEXPD was found to be significant and positive as expected. H3: PRICEREG---->MKTSIZE It was hypothesized that the extent of price controls on pharmaceuticals would be negatively related to market size for pharmaceuticals for a country. In the USITC study, price was found to be inversely related to demand and price elasticities of -1.12 and -1.28 were found suggesting that if the price (in real terms) of pharmaceutical products decreases by 1 percent, the quantity demanded of those products would increase by 1.12 to 1.28 percent (USITC 1991). US's large market for pharmaceuticals is in a large part due to the freedom in pricing that manufacturers enjoy. A recent report by the Council on Competitiveness (1991) emphasized freedom from price control as one of three major factors important for continued competitiveness of the US industry. As the figure illustrates, the relationship between PRICEREG and MKTSIZE was found to be significant and negative as expected. 86 H4: PRICEREG---->R&DEXPD It was hypothesized that the extent of price controls on pharmaceuticals would be negatively related to pharmaceutical R&D expenditure for a country. Pharmaceutical industries in countries with higher prices have more revenues to reinvest in R&D and have generally well-established and stronger R&D programs as compared to industries with lower-priced products (European Chemical News 1989; Redwood 1989; USITC 1991). Price controls in France have been held responsible for the weak domestic industry. In France, much of the costs of drugs for individual patients is reimbursed by the country's social security fund. Since French governments reportedly have kept drug prices artificially low and the industry has traditionally been dependent on its home market for a large share of its revenues, the flow of research funds to companies has been reduced (Chemical Marketing Reporter 1990). As the figure illustrates, the relationship between PRICEREG and R&DEXPD was found to be significant and negative as expected. H5: MKTSIZE---->R&DEXPD It was hypothesized that larger the market size for pharmaceuticals for a country, greater will be its share of global expenditure on pharmaceutical R&D. Pharmaceutical industries in countries with larger markets have more revenues to reinvest in R&D and have generally well-established and stronger R&D programs as compared to industries located in countries with smaller market size (Parker 1984; Pradhan 1983; USITC 1991). As mentioned earlier, developed country industries (having larger country markets) accounted for ninety-six percent of global R&D expenditure on pharmaceuticals whereas the rest of world accounted for just four percent of global research expenses in the period 1980-83 (Redwood 1988). Among the developed countries for example, in the period 87 1980-83, US and Japan were the two largest country markets for pharmaceuticals and simultaneously the top two spenders on pharmaceutical R&D (Redwood 1988). As the figure illustrates, the relationship between MKTSIZE and R&DEXPD was found to be significant and positive as expected. H6: R&DEXPD---->FRGINVST It was hypothesized that greater the expenditure by a country's pharmaceutical industry on R&D, greater will be the extent of foreign investment by the industry. This is because companies look to recouping their investments by seeking new markets. Also more research intensive the company, greater is its propensity to take risks and venture into foreign markets. It is also generally the case that high technology industries are more multinational in nature (Porter 1990; Dosi and Soete 1991; Niosi and Faucher 1991). One study (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992) examined the correlation between R&D expenditures and pharmaceutical exports for 17 industrialized countries and found the rank correlation to be positive and statistically significant. The relationship was also examined at the company level and was found to be significant. Therefore, substantial research expenditures apparently provide the basis for a pharmaceutical industry's international success as reflected in the large share of sales in foreign markets. As the figure illustrates, the relationship between R&DEXPD and FRGINVST was found to be significant and positive as expected. H7: R&DEXPD---->INNOVAT It was hypothesized that greater the expenditure by a country's pharmaceutical industry on R&D, greater will be its success in originating new chemical entities, in other words higher R&D expenditures will lead to greater R&D productivity (Franko 1989). 88 The study carried out by the US International Trade Commission examined the detemrinants of national competitiveness in pharmaceuticals comparing the industry in the US, Western Europe and Japan using a sample of twenty multinational firms. The study found a significant relationship between R&D commitment and NCE origination (USITC 1991). The researchers concluded that "pharmaceutical firms must make a considerable commitment to research and development, both in terms of the size of their R&D budget and R&D staff to remain competitive" (p. 6-5). As the figure illustrates, the relationship between R&DEXPD and INNOVAT was found to be significant and positive as expected. H8: FRGINVST---->INNOVAT It was hypothesized that greater the extent of foreign investment (both exports and FDI) by a country's industry, greater will be the number of NCEs originated by industry. This is because companies that invest abroad are able to exploit the pool of research talents of another country. For example, the Swiss companies in the early 19805 spent almost forty percent of their total research funds abroad (Dunning 1988). American member firms of the Pharmaceutical Manufacturers Association spent about 20 percent of their combined R&D budget in 1980 outside the US. Also, with respect to this particular study, INNOVAT represents not only the number of NCEs originated by a country's pharmaceutical industry in the period 1990- 1994 but also those NCEs that were approved for marketing either at home or abroad. A higher degree of foreign investment should therefore facilitate getting market approval quicker than a lower degree of foreign investment and hence familiarity with foreign markets. An additional factor that motivates locating R&D facilities abroad is that many products have to be sold worldwide to recoup their development costs, and clinical studies conducted in the host country ensure speedier approval for marketing of the product. 89 However as the figure indicates, the relationship between FRGINVST and INN OVAT was found to be significant but negative. Prior studies done with respect to other industries have examined the relationship between degree of internationalization and MNE performance measured as profit-to-sales ratio or some other performance measure (Hymer 1960; Franko 1987; Grant 1987; Thomas and Grant 1987). These studies reported a positive relationship between foreign investment and performance. However, a study done by Geringer et a1. (1989) using a sample of 200 MNEs consisting of the 100 largest firms from the US. and Europe found that as extent of foreign investment increased, performance also increased but it then peaked and exhibited a downward trend. The authors concluded that there is some critical "internationalization threshold" for the companies and that the relationship between degree of internationalization and performance is more complex than previously examined. Several explanations are possible for this phenomenon. As firms encompass increasingly broader geographic markets, the costs associated with geographic dispersion begin escalating thus eroding performance (in this study innovative success). With respect to the pharmaceutical industry, in the recent past, most foreign investment has taken place in the form of licensing or joint venture arrangements for the purposes of market access rather than FDI or investment in foreign R&D laboratories by the multinationals. This could explain why increased foreign penetration may not necessarily result in greater success with originating NCEs. H9: INNOVAT---->GBLSALES It was hypothesized that greater the number of NCEs originated by a country's industry, greater will be its share of global pharmaceutical sales. The relationship between technological innovation and performance has been found to be true of all high technology industries (Rugman 1985; Porter 1990; Niosi 1991). Dozens of studies in econometrics, industrial organization economics, and corporate 90 strategy reveal a significant positive relationship between various indicators of R&D performance/ R&D commitment and performance indicators such as world market share or firm sales growth. Also, according to the technology growth theory, technology is the principal driving force of the growth of industrialized countries, therefore by extension it should also drive the growth of the individual industrial firms based in those countries (Schumpeter 1934; Denison 1967; Carre et al 1975; Harberger 1984). According to Grabowski (1989) - a leading authority on pharmaceutical innovation and competitiveness, "competition in the multinational pharmaceutical industry centers around the discovery and development of important new drug therapies" (p. 27). The USITC study also found a significant positive relationship between number of R&D drugs and global market share of a firm (USITC 1991, p. 5-6). As the figure illustrates, the relationship between INNOVAT and GBLSALES was found to be significant and positive as expected. 5.1.2 Effect ef GNP, Peiee regulation and Industry foeus en Innevatien (see Figure 5.2) H10: GNP---->INDFOCUS It was hypothesized that there is no significant relationship between level of economic development (GNP) of a country and the extent of concentration or focus of its pharmaceutical industry on pharmaceuticals. There is no evidence to suggest that richer country industries are any less diversified or more diversified than poorer country industries. European pharmaceutical firms are more highly diversified than American and Japanese firms in general. This pattern of concentration as against diversification has historical roots rather than any relation to GNP. American and Japanese firms were mainly pharmacy based or 91 Figure 5.2 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Industry focus on Innovation Hypothesized model + w + - + ‘1' ——> significant path .......-.-..........® insignificant path M Result +x ——> significant path ...-......_m.tb insignificant path 92 pharmaceutical in origin, whereas many European firms came into the industry through chemicals and dyestuffs (Redwood 1988). However, as the figure illustrates, the relationship between GNP and IN DFOCUS was found to be significant and negative. A possible explanation for this result is that when both industrialized and developing countries are included in the analysis, the relationship between GNP and INDFOCUS becomes significant since developing country pharmaceutical industries are generally less diversified as compared to the industrialized country industries. For the industrialized group the average percentage of sales that was due to pharmaceuticals in this sample was 63 percent, whereas for the developing country group, the average percentage of sales that was due to pharmaceuticals was 83 percent. H11: PRICEREG---->INDFOCUS It was hypothesized that greater the level of price control on pharmaceuticals, lower would be the concentration of the industry on pharmaceuticals. More favorable the conditions for pharmaceutical profitability, greater would be the focus on sales of pharmaceutical products. However, as the figure illustrates, the relationship between PRICEREG and INDFOCUS was found to be positive instead of negative as expected. Again, this result is possible due to the nature of the sample consisting of both developing and industrialized countries and the large differences in the nature of the industries between the two. The developing countries have a higher degree of price control but are also more focused on pharmaceuticals as compared to the industrialized country group, simply because of the nature of the economic and political conditions, thus resulting in the positive relationship between PRICEREG and INDFOCUS. 93 H12: INDFOCUS---->R&DEXPD It was hypothesized that greater the focus on pharmaceuticals by a country's industry, greater would be the expenditures on pharmaceutical research and development. This is because pharmaceutical industries are generally found to increase their concentration on pharmaceutical related products when the climate for pharmaceutical profitability is favorable. Since R&D is an important aspect of pharmaceutical profitability, therefore by extension a higher focus should result in higher R&D investment. As the figure illustrates, the relationship was positive but insignificant. The insignificance of the relationship could again be attributed to the effect of the developing countries in the sample, i.e., a high focus but low R&D expenditure as compared to the industrialized countries. 5.1.3 _i,' t L' P ' Jalztnmt n 1th ll_ “HOVi (see Figure 5.3) H13: GNP---->INDGRWTH It was hypothesized that there is a positive but insignificant relationship between GNP and industry growth (measured as average percentage change in sales during 1990- 1994). However, as the figure illustrates the relationship between GNP and INDGRWTH was found to be negative but not significant. This could be because the pharmaceutical industry in the developing countries has been growing at a much faster rate (particularly in the recent past) than the industry in the industrialized countries which is fairly stable and well established. For example, the average percentage change in sales for the developing country sample in this study was 13 percent, whereas for the industrialized countries the change was 12 percent. 94 Figure 5.3 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Industry growth on Innovation Hypothesized model + w + - f +/ -—.> significant path --.............£br insignificant path Result __> significant path Hammer» insignificant path 95 H14: PRICEREG---->INDGRWTH It was hypothesized that greater the level of price control on pharmaceuticals, lower would be the average growth in pharmaceutical industry sales for the country. There is anecdotal evidence to suggest that industry sales growth is affected by level of price controls. However as the figure illustrates, the relationship was found to be positive although insignificant This could be due to a couple of reasons. First, countries that have a very profitable industry have also been the ones to be subjected to greater price controls in the recent past thus accounting for the positive direction of the relationship. This is especially true in the case of industrialized countries. The two group analysis discussed later in the chapter reveals this to be the case. Second, as explained above, developing country industries are the ones experiencing greater growth but also have a higher degree of price control as compared to the industrialized countries, thus resulting in the positive direction of the relationship. When the developing countries are analyzed separately as a group the relationship is negative as hypothesized. H15: INDGRWTH---->R&DEXPD It was hypothesized that growth in industry sales would be positively but insignificantly related to R&D expenditures. The link between corporate R&D and firm sales growth has been tested in the industrial organization literature both across and within industries. Results have typically shown an association between measures of R&D input and firm growth (Franko 1989; Scherer 1976; Mansfield 1968; Leonard 1971; Jarrell 1983; Comanor 1986). These studies however used mono-national U.S. samples, so the relationship has not been tested for a world-wide international sample. As the figure illustrates, the relationship was found to be negative and insignificant. Again, the effect of the developing countries in the sample is the possible culprit, i.e., the 96 high industry growth rates in recent years coupled with the lower R&D expenditures in the developing country group when compared to the industrialized group giving us the negative relationship between INDGRWTH and R&DEXPD. Later in the two group analysis it will be seen that the relationship is positive for the industrialized country group alone. 5.1.4 Effect at GNP, Price regulatieu and Industry Qeueeutration on Innevatieu (see Figure 5.4) H16: GNP---->INDCONC It was hypothesized that there is a insignificant relationship between a country's GNP/capita and the concentration of the pharmaceutical industry in that country. This was based on prior literature which showed little difference in the concentration ratios of the industry for countries with varying ranges of economic development. For example Redwood (1988) examined the market share held by the top twenty firms for thirteen industrialized and thirteen developing countries using 1984 data. He found no significant pattern in the relationship between concentration and level of development and concluded that this was because the leading multinational firms have a commanding position in both groups of nations. However, as the figure illustrates, GNP was found to be significantly inversely related to INDCONC, implying that the more developed countries had a less concentrated industry structure. Examination of more recent data on concentration ratios reveals that the degree of oligopoly power is more pronounced in developing countries than the industrialized countries. For example, the 25-firm concentration ratios using 1988 data were compared for industrialized versus developed country groups by Ballance, Pogany and Forstner (1992). The average 25-firm concentration ratio for developing countries was 63 as compared to 57 for the industrialized group. 97 Figure 5.4 Effect of GNP, Price regulation and Indusz concentration on Innovation Hypothesized model + w + - + @+ w ———> significant path ----—F insignificant path Result ———-> significant path -—-—--—br insignificant path 98 A possible reason for this difference is that the domestic industry in the poorer countries is relatively weak along with the incomplete regulatory system in these countries which allows abuse of market power by the multinationals. The implications of this are however worrying for policy makers and consumers in the developing world. H17: PRICEREG---->INDCONC It was hypothesized that there is no significant relationship between degree of price control and industry concentration for a country. This is because there is lack of any research study with respect to the pharmaceutical industry that examines the above relationship even with single country samples, let alone multicountry samples such as this one. Although the industrial organization and economics literature generally points to the negative effects of regulation on market competition (Kamien and Schwartz 1982; Rothwell and Zegveld 1981), there was insufficient anecdotal or empirical evidence with respect to the pharmaceutical industry that the relationship would be significant. As the figure illustrates, PRICEREG had a positive but insignificant impact on INDCONC. H18: INDCONC---->R&DEXPD The relationship between market structure and indicators of innovation has been statistically tested by industrial organization economists. Schumpeter's hypothesis that a "competitive oligopoly" is most conducive to innovation provided the impetus for several studies in this area (Niosi 1991). Other researchers also argued a similar position, the argument being that since research is generally not a profitable activity, only sufficiently large firms can carry out research knowing they will benefit from its results (Villard 1958; Phillips 1956; Kamien and Schwartz 1970; Loury 1979). 99 Experts in the pharmaceutical industry also generally concede to the oligopolistic characteristics of the industry due to its research intensive nature (Grabowski 1976; Schwartzman 1976). Based on the above, it was therefore hypothesized that INDCONC would be positively related to R&DEXPD. As the figure illustrates, the relationship was found to be negative although insignificant. However, as will be discussed later, the two-group analysis revealed a positive relationship between INDCONC and R&DEXPD. That is, when the industrialized and developing country samples are tested separately, the relationship is in the direction as expected. Therefore, pooling the two groups results in confounding effects for certain variables. 5.1.5 Eff t, 'H latt Artrtv: tt‘ in, AL! .' __ ‘ It titvztt (see Figure 5.5) H19: POP---->MKTSIZE Generally larger the population, greater is the market size for pharmaceuticals. As expected the relationship was positive and significant. H20: POP---->R&DEXPD Larger populations should result in larger market size (as explained above) and consequently greater revenues to invest in R&D. It was therefore hypothesized that more populated countries would be associated with greater levels of expenditure on pharmaceutical R&D. As the figure shows, the relationship was positive and significant as expected. Figure 5.5 Effect of Population, Approval time and Market size on Innovation Hypothesized model + __.’ significant Path “mm-a» insignificant path + w 4. + Result ——5 significant path ~--~---+ insignificant path 101 H21: APPTIME---->MKTSIZE Intuitively, a high degree of regulation should have a negative effect on market size. That is, greater the stringency of the approval procedure for marketing of new pharmaceuticals, longer it will take for the new product to reach the market, thus reducing market availability of new products and therefore reducing potential market size. Therefore, a negative relationship was hypothesized between APPTIME and MKTSIZE. However, as the figure illustrates, APPTIME was positively associated with MKTSIZE although the path was statistically insignificant. Most studies in the pharmaceutical industry literature have examined the relation of APPTIME to innovation rate. The only study examining the APPTIME---->MKTSIZE relationship is by Parker (1984), where be ranked countries by regulatory tightness and examined a series of rank correlations between the former and various indicators of market size. All correlations were significant and positive. This is because countries that have large markets for pharmaceuticals are also the ones which are most stringent in their approval procedures for marketing of new pharmaceuticals thus possibly explaining the above result. H22: APPTIME---->R&DEXPD Delays in the marketing approval process can reduce a product's effective patent life thus reducing the period in which a company can recoup its R&D expenditures. Studies done on pharmaceutical innovation indicate the negative effects of long approval times on the rate of innovation (Grabowski and Vernon 1976; Baily 1972; Grabowski, Vernon and Thomas 1976; Wardell 1973; 1975). APPTIME should therefore have a negative effect on R&DEXPD. However, as the figure illustrates, the relationship was positive although statistically insignificant. Again, the confounding effect of the sample was suspected. That is, industrialized countries have longer approval times but also larger R&D expenditures as compared to developing 102 countries resulting in the positive relationship. When two group analysis was done, the effect was negative but insignificant for the two groups (I & D). 5.1.6 Effeet at Papulatien, Appzeval time and Industry feeus an Innovatian (see Figure 5.6) H23: POP---->INDFOCUS It was hypothesized that larger the population, greater would be the focus of the industry on pharmaceuticals due to the larger market for pharmaceuticals. The relationship was found to be positive and significant as expected. H24: APPTIME---->INDFOCUS There is little in the literature to suggest that regulatory stringency has a direct effect on the level of industry focus or diversification. Therefore it was hypothesized that the effect would be negative but statistically insignificant. As the figure illustrates, the hypothesis was confirmed. 5.1.7Effc fP ultin vlim nInutr rwhn mm (see Figure 5.7) H25: POP---->INDGRWTH It was hypothesized that a larger population size would have a positive effect on growth in industry sales, however, the effect would not be statistically significant. As the figure illustrates, the above hypothesis was confirmed. 103 Figure 5.6 Effect of Population, Approval time and Industry focus on Innovation Hypothesized model 4g». + ——-D significant path / a» insignificant path ' . INDRIUS Result -——-> significant path W4» insignificant path 104 Figure 5.7 Effect of Population, Approval time and IndusU'y growth on Innovation Hypothesized model —> significant path M insignificant path Result ——p significant path 4» insignificant path 105 H26: APPTIME---->INDGRWTH As mentioned earlier, the relationship between APPI‘HVIE and rate of innovation has been the subject of examination by most researchers. One can speculate that a higher rate of innovation would fuel higher sales growth and therefore approval times should affect INDGRWTH. Based on the above, it was hypothesized that APPTIME is negatively related to INDGRWTH. However, as the figure illustrates, the relationship was found to be positive but insignificant. This may be because, approval times for most countries have remained fairly stable atleast for the past decade, rendering it difficult to isolate the effect of changes in regulatory approval times on changes in sales growth. A longer time frame would be needed to isolate this effect. 5.1.8 __ - f It- lin Arut 1111‘ In _ JD nr in . Fereigu Cammitment an Innovatieu (see Figure 5.8) H27: POP---->INDCONC Theoretically, in a competitive industry, a larger market size should stimulate more entries into the industry. Therefore, if a large population translates to a larger potential market, then INDCONC should be lower as POP is higher. However, no firm conclusions are possible due to the oligopolistic nature of the global pharmaceutical industry in individual countries. It was therefore hypothesized that there is a negative but insignificant relationship between POP and INDCONC. As the figure illustrates, the relationship is positive but insignificant. The positive direction of the relationship could be explained due to the inclusion of the developing countries in the sample which have a much larger population but also show higher INDCONC as compared to industrialized countries. Two group analysis (discussed 106 Figure 5.8 Effect of Population, Approval time, Industry concentration and Foreign Commitment on Innovation Hypothesized model ——> significant path we» insignificant path Result —-> significant path MM insignificant path later in this se industrialized 328: APP'I As mer been the suhje stringent app resulting in g; Howt global phar multination; but insignif the relation H29: R8 It ' country's] 10 invegm Tl Possible. TClalionS] home ma [ho-Se Wit F dense m became hand She 107 later in this section) reveals a negative relationship between POP and INDCON C for the industrialized countries as would be expected. H28: APPTIME---->INDCONC As mentioned earlier, the relationship between APPTIME and rate of innovation has been the subject of frequent examination by most researchers. One can speculate that more stringent approval procedures would deter firms from entering the industry therefore resulting in greater industry concentration. However, no firm conclusions are possible due to the oligopolistic nature of the global pharmaceutical industry in individual countries and the domination of a few multinational firms in most countries. It was therefore hypothesized that there is a positive but insignificant relationship between APPTIME and INDCONC. As the figure illustrates, the relationship is positive but insignificant. H29: R&DEXPD---->FRGCOMM It was hypothesized that level of investment in research and development by a country's pharmaceutical industry would be positively associated with level of commitment to investment in overseas markets. This is because firms need to recoup their R&D investment in as many ways as possible, one of which is greater sales in foreign markets. As the figure shows, the relationship was found to be positive but insignificant. This can be explained on basis of home market size. Countries whose industries show a high percentage of foreign sales are those with relatively smaller domestic markets. For example, industries in countries like Switzerland, Belgium, Denmark etc., derive more than eighty percent of their pharmaceutical sales from non-domestic sources because of their smaller home market size. Countries such as US and Japan on the other hand show a much smaller degree of foreign commitment due to their huge home markets. 108 Thus R&D investment does impact the absolute level of foreign investment (see H6) but not necessarily the level of foreign commitment expressed as share of foreign to total sales. H30: FRGCOMM---->INNOVAT Despite the multinational character of the industry, most of the basic research is still done in the laboratories of the home country. A higher level of commitment to foreign markets may not therefore necessarily result in greater innovative success. In fact it could have the opposite effect of diverting attention and resources away from basic research to the increased complexity of managing diverse foreign investments. This was found to be the case in H8 (FRGWVST---->NNOVAT). Another factor is the knowledge and familiarity required with the local FDA approval procedures. Most FDA agencies are likely to approve home country applications quicker than applications from foreign companies. INNOVAT in this study represents not only the number of new NCEs originated by a country's industry but those NCEs that were approved for marketing either at home or abroad. INNOVAT is likely to be higher when most of the NCEs have been originated and approved for marketing in the same country. Therefore, it was hypothesized that the relationship between FRGCOMM and INN OVAT would be negative but insignificant. The figure shows that the hypothesis was confirmed. 5.2 1| _' I -,_.LL _-’ D .Ti__i_._ _"1\_" 1'“; The sample of twenty-seven countries was divided into two groups. The countries were classified based on Ballance, Pogany and Forstner's (1992) classification of countries' pharmaceutical industries. The above researchers grouped countries into four 109 groups (A, B, C and D) based on the technological sophistication of a country's pharmaceutical industry'. The country sample in this study was divided into two groups. Group 1 consisted of Group A countries which were mostly industrialized countries (fifteen in all) and Group 2 consisted of Group B and C countries which were mostly developing countries (twelve in all). The research question of interest here was: is there a difference in the direction and magnitude of influence of various factors that affect innovation and hence global competitiveness of the pharmaceutical industry of industrialized nations versus that of the developing nations? Again, thirty-two runs on EQS were carried out with the two groups (Tables in Appendix A show the results of the 32 program runs). Table 5.1 lists the paths which were significantly different in the two groups. N 0 specific hypotheses for the two-group analysis were developed since this analysis was exploratory in nature due to lack of similar studies in the literature. The paths for which significant differences were found are discussed below. (a) GNP---->MKTSIZE The gross national product of a country was found to have a significant positive effect on the market size for pharmaceuticals for the industrialized (1) country group. The relationship was insignificant and negative for the developing (D) country group. This effect seen for the D-group can be explained based on the nature of the health care systems in developing countries. First, poorer developing countries spend a greater proportion of their health care budget on pharmaceuticals. There is also greater public expenditure on pharmaceuticals in the relatively poorer developing countries (especially the Third World countries). Thus GNP of a developing country may not be a significant factor 1Group A - Countries with a sophisticated pharmaceutical industry and a significant research base, Group B - Countries with innovative capabilities, Group C - Countries with reproductive capabilities and Group D - Countries without a pharmaceutical indusu'y. 110 Table 5.1: Significant Path Differences Between Industrialized (I) and Deve10ping (D) Country Groups Path Significance Direction I D I (l) GNP-->MKTSIZE Significant Insignificant + (2) PRICEREG---->R&DEXPD Significant Insignificant - (3) MKTSIZE ----- >R&DEXPD Significant Insignificant + (4) R&DEXPD-~——>INNOVAT Significant Insignificant + (5) FRGINVST-—-->INNOVAT Significant Insignificant - (6) INNOVAT-——>GBLSALES Significant Insignificant + (7) PRICEREG----->INDCONC Significant Insignificant - (8) INDCONC-«->R&DEXPD Insignificant Significant + (9) POP ----- >R&DEXPD Significant Insignificant + (10) POP----->INDFOCUS Significant Insignificant + rum—— in deterrrr oi reduei (h) PR‘ expent D-gro the it more indu man 101 ch: 1c 111 in determining market size for pharmaceuticals and may well have a negative effect by way of reducing public health expenditures on pharmaceuticals. (b) PRICEREG---->R&DEXPD The level of price controls on pharmaceuticals had a significant negative effect on expenditures on R&D for the I-group but the effect was opposite and insignificant for the D-group. This difference is not surprising in view of the fact that pharmaceutical industries in the industrialized countries are heavily research based and their R&D activities would be more sensitive to future profits and therefore pricing regulation. The pharmaceutical industries in the D-group are not based on basic research but concentrate heavily on the manufacture of bulk pharmaceuticals and formulations. The positive (although insignificant) effect observed for the D-group could be due to the presence of Group B type countries which do have a small research base but are also characterized by greater price regulation. (c) MKTSIZE ----- >R&DEXPD A larger market for pharmaceuticals had a strong positive effect on innovation investment, i.e., R&D expenditures for the I-group; the effect was insignificant and negative for the D-group. This result is indicative of the vast difference in the nature of the pharmaceutical industries in the two groups. As explained earlier, the research-based industry in the industrialized countries will be more sensitive to the underlying factors affecting innovation as compared to the industry in the developing countries. Since research is a costly and time-consuming process, market size would greatly affect the level of investment in research. Ho higher luv: the result. protectior drug dew greater 1 technolc of bulk ‘ (d) R8 SUCCCSE the LE dueto Statist inabil gr on; (e) F grOUI ReQe explt path 112 However, a larger market in developing countries does not necessarily mean a higher investment in innovation and may even reduce the investment in R&D as shown by the result. This may be because of several reasons. For example, the absence of patent protection in countries in the D- group reduces the incentive for spending on R&D for new drug development. A larger market size in the such countries would therefore result in greater concentration of efforts in other activities such as improving manufacturing technology for basic chemicals, acquiring distribution channels, greater foreign exporting of bulk formulations, etc. ((1) R&DEXPD---->INNOVAT The level of investment in innovation has a strong positive effect on innovative success for the I-group countries; the effect is insignificant and negative for the D-group. This implies that investment in R&D is more efficiently and productively utilized in the I-group than in the D-group. The difference is not surprising as previously explained due to the research-based nature of the industry in the I-group. The negative effect of R&D expenditure on innovation for the D-group was not statistically significant but is important for interpretation purposes, since it indicates either inability to utilize R&D resources efficiently or that R&D resources in countries in the D- group are more efficiently utilized in other activities rather than basic research. (e) FRGINVST---->INNOVAT The level of foreign investment had a strong negative effect on innovation for the I- group; the effect was insignificant and positive for the D-group. The pharmaceutical industry of industrialized countries is multinational in character. Recent cost-containment pressures in national markets has driven the industry further to explore alternative markets abroad. However, as explained in the discussion of the above path for the overall group analysis, over-expansion into foreign markets can result in 113 diversion of resources from basic research to managerial activities, thus affecting innovative success (INN OVAT). The same is not true for developing country industries, since their extent of foreign involvement is restricted to exports of mainly bulk formulations and generic pharmaceuticals. Besides, the industry is not primarily research based in this group, thus the insignificant effect of FRGINV ST on INN OVAT for the D—group is not surprising. (f) INNOVAT---->GBLSALES The number of new drugs developed (INN OVAT) has a strong positive effect on global competitiveness (GBLSALES) of the pharmaceutical industries in the I-group. The effect is insignificant and negative for the D-group. This result has serious implications for developing countries and challenges the generalized assumption in the literature that all countries (regardless of their stage of economic development) need to invest in innovation for global competitiveness. The negative and insignificant relationship between IN N OVAT and GBLSALES for the D—group implies that there are other avenues by which developing country industries can be globally competitive and that, atleast for now, ability to develop NCEs is not one of them. The prospects and strategies that developing countries should follow are discussed in greater detail in the final chapter on conclusions. (g) PRICEREG---->INDCONC Price regulation had a strong negative effect on extent of industry concentration for the I-group countries; the effect was insignificant for the D-group. The strong significant effect of regulation on market structure in industrialized countries versus the weak effect of regulation in the developing countries is expected, since the markets for pharmaceuticals are larger and more competitive in the developed 114 economies. However, the negative effect of PRICEREG is surprising since greater price pressure should result in higher concentration in the industry. However, this effect is plausible, due to the presence of competition from the generic pharmaceutical industry. Greater price control on patented drugs (as is normally the case in I-group countries) will induce more generic firms to enter the industry thus possibly lowering overall concentration ratios for the industry. (h) INDCONC---->R&DEXPD Industry concentration levels had a significant positive effect on level of R&D expenditures for the D-group countries; the effect was insignificant for the I-group. In recent years, the pharmaceutical industry in the developing countries has been experiencing increasing concentration ratios, this upward trend has been more pronounced for the developing countries than the industrialized countries where the ratio has remained fairly stable. Pharmaceutical industries in the developing world have been increasing spending on research, and as we have seen earlier the oligopolistic nature of the industry is especially favorable for greater research spending. Thus, the level of concentration in the developing countries which are still dominated by a handful of multinationals has a more significant effect on level of R&D expenditures than seen in the industrialized countries where there is not as much variation with respect to concentration ratios in the sample. (i) POP---->R&DEXPD Population size has a strong positive effect on research spending in the industry for the industrialized countries; the effect is insignificant and negative for the developing countries. A larger population for an industrialized country translates into a larger market size for pharmaceuticals; the same is not true for developing countries as the more populated 115 developing countries are characterized by low purchasing power. A larger market size should therefore be associated with greater spending on R&D for the I-group countries, which is the effect observed in this case. Therefore, pharmaceutical industries in large industrialized countries such as the US are at an advantage, compared to industries in small industrialized countries such as Switzerland with a small home market. (j) POP---->INDFOCUS Population size was significantly associated with level of industry focus for the I- group countries; the effect was insignificant for the D-group. A larger population as explained above in industrialized countries implies a larger home market. Larger the market for pharmaceuticals, greater should be the focus of the industry on pharmaceutical products than on non-pharmaceuticals. This also explains why the pharmaceutical industry in countries like US and Japan with larger home markets have less diversified pharmaceutical industries than countries such as Switzerland or Belgium with more diversified pharmaceutical industries due to their small home markets. v I v ' he Di r n w I- - In general, the global innovation model showed a better fit for the industrialized group than for the developing country group in terms of the number of significant paths found. This result is interesting and has serious implications for further research with respect to economic development. Most research done on industrialized country samples generalizes the findings to developing countries since data on developing countries is scarce. This study results show that generalization of models and findings used for industrialized countries cannot be universally applied. According to Lall (1990), a leading expert on economic development and an advisor to the OECD, developed economies have often tried to apply the same neoclassical 116 principles to developing countries with negative results. The structure of incentives, factor markets, policies, institution and infrastructure in the developing countries is far too different to be subjected to the same economic policies as those applied to the industrialized econonries. In addition, differing social, economic, political and cultural traditions cast their own influence on the direction and pace of capability development. A study by Fagerberg (1987) tested the technology gap models using a sample of OECD and non-OECD countries, where he examined the relationship between technology variables such as growth in innovative activity and economic development of the country. He found the models "better suited" for industrialized countries than the developed countries. He concluded that the developing countries have followed a separate way of development and that if differences in growth between these countries had to be explained, a much more detailed analysis of "economic, social and institutional structures needed to be carried out" (p. 64). 5.3 I I NT INDIRE T EFFE T I VATI A D WES Several constructs had significant indirect effects on innovation and global sales (global competitiveness). As seen in Figure 5.9, pharmaceutical innovation (INNOVAT) was affected by a country's macroeconomic environment (GNP and POP); the regulatory environment (PRICEREG); and its market/industry structure (MKTSIZE). Both GNP and POP had significant positive effects on innovation, implying that pharmaceutical industries based/located in countries with a higher GNP/capita and a larger Population are more successful at developing NCEs. 117 Figure 5.9 Significant Indirect Effects 118 PRICEREG had a significant negative indirect effect on innovation as expected, i.e., the less favorable the regulatory environment in a country for its pharmaceutical industry, lower is the innovative success of the industry. The home market size (MKTSIZE) of a country had a significant positive effect on innovation; i.e., industries based in countries with a large market potential for pharmaceuticals are more successful at developing and introducing innovative new drugs (NCEs). Global competitiveness (GBLSALES) was also indirectly affected by a country's economic environment (GNP and POP); regulatory environment (PRICEREG); market/industry structure (MKTSIZE); investment in innovation (R&DEXPD); and the level of foreign investment (FRGINVST). In general, pharmaceutical industries based in countries with a higher gross national product per capita, larger population, lower price regulation, larger market size, higher investment in research and development, and moderate foreign investment were more globally competitive. 5.4 L A DIF INM L-RE LT As discussed in Chapter 4, the global diffusion model had several constructs in common with the global innovation model since several of the factors that affect supply also affect demand. In all, seven paths were of interest in the global diffusion model as listed in Table 4.3b. To test for the seven hypothesized paths, twelve separate runs on EQS were carried out. Appendix B shows the table of results for the global diffusion model. The global diffusion model was tested only for the industrialized group of countries since few developing countries in the sample were recipients of new drug introductions. 119 Thus results of the global diffusion model apply only to the industrialized group of countries. Figure 5.10 shows the results of the global diffusion analysis. The hypotheses specific to the diffusion model are discussed below. H1: IN DF OCUS---->MKTPOT It was hypothesized that a higher industry focus on pharmaceutical products would be positively associated with market potential. As the figure illustrates, this hypothesis was confirmed. The underlying causal effects on market potential are important when analyzing diffusion models, since larger markets should attract greater diffusion of new products. Thus foreign pharmaceutical firms can benefit by choosing countries which show a higher overall industry focus on pharmaceuticals when introducing new drugs. A higher host country focus on pharmaceuticals can also have other positive effects such as greater familiarity of regulatory agencies with new drug development procedures, pricing mechanisms, and other public policy issues related to pharmaceuticals. H2: INDGRWTH---->MKTPOT Industry growth was found to have an insignificant effect on market potential. This is because most industrialized countries have had fairly stable growth rates in recent years with not much variation among the countries with respect to growth rates. Therefore market potential is not significantly affected by growth in sales of the pharmaceutical industry. However, even though the relationship is insignificant, positive grth reflects a healthy industry and therefore a viable market. Pharmaceutical firms will in general be better off introducing their products into countries where the pharmaceutical industry shows positive percentage changes in annual sales. 120 Figure 5.10 Global Diffusion Model $1" ——> significant path M insignificant path “WP“ INDmCUS 121 H3: INDCONC---->MKTPOT Level of industry concentration was insignificantly related to market potential. It was hypothesized that countries with industries characterized by greater concentration would be associated with smaller market size for pharmaceuticals. However, the relationship between industry concentration and market size is not established in the literature. Due to the supposedly oligopolistic nature of the industry, it is difficult to predict the effect of concentration on market potential. Therefore, foreign pharmaceutical companies looking to introduce products in other countries should not be deterred by concentration ratios of the industry in those countries, since there still could be a large untapped market out there for investment. H4: MKTPOT---->INFRGN A larger market potential was hypothesized to have a significant positive effect on inbound foreign investment. As shown in the figure, the hypothesis was confirmed. Larger markets are bound to attract greater foreign investment into the industry. US is a particularly attractive market and has attracted a great deal of foreign investment by Swiss, British and other Western European pharmaceutical firms. H5: MKTPOT---->DIFF It was hypothesized that market potential would have a significant positive effect on the number of NCEs introduced into the country (DIFF). However as the figure illustrates, the relationship was insignificant. This could be explained on the basis of Parker's study (Parker 1984) where he found that larger markets did not necessarily attract more new drug introductions than smaller markets. He speculated that such an effect was possible because most large country markets are also the ones with the most stringent regulatory procedures, thus the effect of regulation canceled out the effect of market size. 122 In this study DH7F represents the number of new drugs launched for the first time in any country. Generally pharmaceutical companies choose those countries for first launch of a new drug, whose regulatory procedures they are most familiar with. Usually this is the home country, however there can be exceptions such as the US where in recent years more US based companies choose other countries for first launch due to the unusually long approval periods in the US. Once the drug has achieved market success in the country of first launch, then it is generally easier for the firm to obtain approval for marketing in other more attractive (larger market size) countries. Therefore, a higher MKTPOT may not necessarily be positively related to DIFF in this case. H6: IN FRGN ----- >DIFF It was hypothesized that greater the incoming foreign investment in the country's pharmaceutical industry, higher will be the number of NCEs introduced into the country. This is, because firms would invest in countries which offer attractive returns in terms of large market size or easier approval procedures or to exploit local talent in research or other areas. Some of the above factors would favor NCE introduction into the country's markets. As the figure shows, the relationship was positive but insignificant. As explained in the previous hypothesis, a firm's choice of the country for first launch of an NCE depends on a complex set of factors, especially a combination of various regulatory policies such as patent protection policies, product liability issues, acceptance of foreign clinical data, etc. In this study, only two regulatory variables were used, namely price control and approval time for marketing of NCE. Although it would have been desirable to test as many regulatory variables as possible, constraints on data availability and other resources made this difficult. 123 Also increasingly in the past, most foreign investment by pharmaceutical companies has been in the form of informal alliance arrangements, such as licensing or other marketing agreements for gaining market access for drugs that have already been approved elsewhere. Therefore, extent of inbound foreign investment may lead to greater number of first time NCE launches, but the effect may be insignificant due to the above factors. H7 : INNOVAT---->DIFF It was hypothesized that a higher number of NCEs developed by a country's pharmaceutical industry (INNOVAT) would be associated with higher number of NCEs first launched into the country (DIFF). This is because as explained previously, most firms choose the home country or the country in which the NCE was developed (originating country) as the country for first launch. This is due to the ease in getting marketing approval from the local regulatory agency. This could also be explained on basis of demand creating supply. A higher perceived demand for a product would lead a firm to develop such a product for that market in which it is located, thus making it more likely for the originating country to be the recipient country for the NCE. As the figure illustrates, INNOVAT had a strong positive effect on DIFF confirming the relationship between supply and demand factors of innovation. 5.5 W The results of the global innovation model analysis provide interesting insights into the factors affecting innovation in the pharmaceutical industry. A country's economic, regulatory and market/industry environment has significant effects on the innovativeness of its pharmaceutical industry. The results also indicate that greater innovation overall leads to 124 greater global competitiveness. Analysis of the GIM model also reveals the need for analyzing the industrialized and developing countries separately. Two-group analysis of the industrialized and developing countries reveals significant differences between the determinants of innovation for the two groups. In general, the GIM model shows a better fit for the industrialized countries and a poor fit for the developing country group. The managerial and public policy implications of the above results are discussed in Chapter 6. Global innovation and global competitiveness are significantly affected indirectly by a number of factors. In general, pharmaceutical industries based in countries with a higher gross national product per capita, larger population, lower price regulation, larger market size, higher investment in research and development, and moderate foreign investment were more globally competitive. Results of the global diffusion model analysis revealed that level of global innovation had a far greater impact on the extent of diffusion of NCEs into a country than the market potential or level of inbound foreign investment for the country. This relationship confirms the theory that supply and demand factors of innovation strongly affect each other. The result also implies that factors that impact global innovation can also impact global diffusion. Table 5.2 provides an overall summary of the results for the three groups analyzed (I+D; I; and D) for the global innovation model. 125 Table 5.2: Summary of Results Global Innovation Analysis Path relationships (1) Economic Env ----> I+D Mkt/Industry structure GNP---> Mkt size 5i g GNP-->Industry focus 5i g GNP-->Industry growth insi g GNP-->Industry conc si g Population-~->Mkt size si g Population-->Industry focus si g Population-->Industry growth insig Population-->Industry conc insi g (2) Economic Env----> Innovation Investment GNP—--->R&D Expend sig Population---> R&D Expend si g (3) Regulatory Env----> Mkt/Industry Structure Price control---> Mkt size sig Price control--->Indusu'y focus si g Price control-->Industry growth insi g Price control-->Industry conc insi g Approval time--->Mkt size insi g Approval time--->Indusuy focus insi g Approval time-->Industry growth insig Approval time-«>Industry conc insi g (4) Regulation----> Innovation Investment Price control--—>R&D Expend 51 g Approval time-«> R&D Expend insi g (5) Mkt/Industry structure----> Innovation Investment Mkt size--->R&D Expend si g Industry focus»-—>R&D Expend in si g Industry growth—«>R&D Expend insig Industry conc—-—>R&D Expend insig insig sig sig insig insig insig sig sig insig insig sig sig insig sig insig sig insig insig insig insig sig insig sig insig insig Significance of Paths D insig insig insig insig sig insig insig insig 5i g insig insig insig insig insig insig insig insig insig insig insig insig insig insig Direction I+D I + + - + + + + + + + + - + + + + + + + + + _ + + + + + + + + + - + + + + - + - + ++ ++++ Table 5.2 (cont'd) 126 (6) Innovation Investment ---> Foreign Investment R&DExpend---> frgn invst R&D Expend-~> frgn com (7) Innovation Invst--> Global Innovation R&DExpend——>Innovat (8) Foreign Invst---> Global Innovation Frgn invst---->Innovat Frgn comm-~->Innovat (9) Global Innovation---> Global Sales Innovat ------ > Gbl Sales I+D I sig sig insig insig sig sig sig sig insig sig sig sig insig 5i g insig insig insig insig I+D CHAPTER SIX CONCLUSIONS This chapter has five sections. The first section provides a summary of the results of the study. Section 6.2 discusses the managerial and public policy implications of the study results for industrialized and developing countries. Section 6.3 examines the theoretical, empirical, and methodological contributions of the study. Section 6.4 presents the study limitations. The last section has suggestions for future research. 6.1 M RY RE LT 6.1.1 Deteeminants ef filehal Innovatiuu One of the research objectives of the study was: Which country factors stimulate or inhibit a nation's pharmaceutical industry to be globally innovative? The mautfiudimgs as a result of the analyses of the global innovation models are listed below. (1) The economic environment of a country has a significant impact on the market and industry structure of its pharmaceutical industry as well as on pharmaceutical innovation investment. (2) The regulatory environment of a country has a significant effect on pharmaceutical market and industry structure as well as on pharmaceutical innovation investment. (3) A large market size for pharmaceuticals is associated with greater investment in pharmaceutical innovation. (4) Increases in innovation investment lead to increased global innovation. (5) Only moderate levels of foreign investment lead to increased global innovation. A high level of foreign diversification has a negative effect on global innovation. 127 128 (6) Global innovation is positively associated with global competitiveness, i.e., greater the number of NCEs developed, greater is the global market share of the country's industry. (7) Global competitiveness of the pharmaceutical industry was significantly indirectly affected by it's national economic, regulatory and market/industry envrronments. Of the economic variables, GNP had a greater effect on market and industry structure variables than POP. Market size, industry focus and industry concentration were all affected by economic factors. Industry growth was the only aspect of market/industry structure which was not influenced. Both GNP and POP also affected R&DEXPD. Of the regulatory variables, only PRICEREG was significant. APPTIME did not have a significant effect on any of the dependent variables. Pricing regulation had a strong negative effect on market size. It also affected industry focus. Pricing regulation also had the effect of lowering innovation investment. Market size was the only significant variable of all the market/industry structure variables to have an effect on innovation investment. A larger pharmaceutical market size had the effect of increasing investment in innovation. Higher levels of innovation investment seemed to drive higher levels of total foreign investment and global innovation. Finally, global innovation was a strong determinant of global competitiveness. 6.1.2 filahal Innavatien Factars far Industrialized vetsus Develeplug W The mainjndlugs as a result of analyzing the two groups (industrialized and developing) of countries are presented below. (1) The economic environment of industrialized countries had a greater impact on the market and industry structure of its pharmaceutical industry as well as on pharmaceutical innovation investment, as compared to developing countries. (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) 129 The regulatory environment of industrialized countries had a more significant effect on pharmaceutical market and industry structure as well as on pharmaceutical innovation investment, as compared to developing countries. A large market size for pharmaceuticals is associated with greater investment in pharmaceutical innovation in the case of industrialized country firms; the effect is negative and not significant for developing country firms. Increases in innovation investment lead to increased global innovation for the industrialized counuy industries; the effect is negative and not significant for the developing country industries. A high level of foreign investment has a negative effect on global innovation for industrialized countries; the effect is opposite but insignificant for developing country industries. Global innovation drives global competitiveness of industrialized country firms; but has a negative although insignificant effect on developing country competitiveness. Global innovation in the pharmaceutical industry in industrialized countries is significantly inditectly affected by it's national economic, regulatory and market/industry environments; no significant indirect effects are obtained for the developing country industries. In general, the global innovation model had a better fit for the I—group in terms of the number of significant paths than for the D-group. More significantly, perhaps, none of the direct causal variables of global innovation and global competitive advantage had any significant effects for the developing country group. This implies that factors other than those related to innovation are responsible for global competitive advantage of the developing country pharmaceutical industries. Also a second important implication of the above findings is that results for industrialized country markets cannot be generalized to developing country markets both for managerial and especially for public policy purposes. 6.1.3 e ' l I Diffui A second research objective of the study was: Which country factors stimulate or inhibit diffusion of pharmaceutical innovations into its markets? The global diffusion model 130 was analyzed only for I-group, therefore the results apply only to industrialized countries. The mundiugs are listed below. (1) The nation's economic, regulatory and market/industry environment, all had a significant effect on the market potential for diffusion of NCEs. (2) Greater market potential for pharmaceutical diffusion led to increased inbound foreign investment into a country's pharmaceutical industry. (3) Global diffusion of pharmaceuticals was not directly affected by market potential or inbound foreign investment but was strongly affected by the level of global innovation. With respect to the economic environment, only GNP had a significant effect on market potential for diffusion. The effect of Population size was absent. Of the regulatory variables, only PRICEREG was an important factor affecting market potential, APPTIME had no effect. Of the market/industry structure variables, industry focus was the only factor significantly affecting market potential. Contrary to expectations, global innovation was a more significant explanatory variable of global diffusion than market potential and inbound foreign investment. That is, countries characterized by a highly innovative pharmaceutical industry were also more likely to be recipients of pharmaceutical innovations. That is, NCE originating countries are also the destination countries for NCEs. 6.2 W 6.2.1 mm: Although the study examines factors affecting competitiveness at the national level and some at the industry level, the results have implications at the firm level since both national level policies can affect firm strategy as well as vice versa. Managerial implications of study results for firms from industrialized countries and developing 131 countries are discussed separately due to significant differences found between the two groups. 6.2.1.1 i f r n iz nt As discussed in Chapter 3 in the Review of Literature, the global strategic management literature was reviewed to draw implications for pharmaceutical MNCs from the study results. Three streams of thought in the literature were found to be applicable to this study. These were: (1) Core Competencies, (2) Comparative advantage-based competitive advantage and (3) Collaborate to compete. (1) WM: As defined earlier, core competencies are "the collective learning in the organization, especially the coordination of diverse production skills and integration of multiple streams of technology" (Prahalad and Hamel 1990, p. 82). According to most experts in global strategy and competitiveness, firms must possess some core competency which is difficult for competitors to imitate in order to have sustained competitive advantage. The results of this study show that ability to innovate is causally related to global sales or global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. Further, the environment for innovation is affected by the home country's economic, regulatory and market/industry environments. Thus the key to competitive advantage for industrialized country pharmaceutical fums will be in developing core competencies in R&D as well as being able to strategically manage their R&D programs with respect to changing economic, regulatory and market/industry conditions of the countries in which they operate. A good example would be the Japanese MNCs. In response to a stagnating economy, increasing price pressures from the Japanese government, and greater foreign competition in the home markets, several Japanese pharmaceutical firms have in the recent past invested heavily in R&D research units in the US and abroad, along with marketing 132 agreements with major US and European multinational companies involving licensing and co-marketing agreements (Yoshikawa 1989). Several US multinationals are now focusing their R&D efforts on only a few therapeutic categories with more research being disease-based rather than symptom-based. This is in response to the increasing costs of research and the increasing regulatory and competitive pressure such as competition from generic manufacturers (Financial World 1989). A second area of core competency in the pharmaceutical industry is in marketing (Bogner and Thomas 1992). Analysis of the global diffusion model revealed that the market potential for diffusion is significantly affected by a nation's economic, regulatory and market/industry environments. Thus selection of international markets for investment or introduction of new products should be undertaken only after a careful evaluation of the above environmental factors. Firms can develop core competencies with respect to being able to identify changes in environmental conditions for investment purposes. The dynamic environment in the European Community offers an especially appropriate illustration of the above problem. Due to the unification of the European community markets and the effort towards harmonizing the various environments, pharmaceutical firms in the EC have been faced with great uncertainties with respect to future market conditions. Firms that can strategically manage their marketing programs in coordination with these changing environmental conditions will be at a distinct competitive advantage in the future. An example to illustrate the above, is the alliances developed by small local companies in the EC to attract foreign multinationals for licensing purposes. For example, Derma Alliance is an alliance of dermatological companies comprising of small local firms from Norway, UK, Germany, Spain and France, formed in direct response to the changing EC environment. The idea of this alliance is to offer big multinationals development, regulatory and marketing help (Longman 1994) with their licensed products. By licensing 133 a product to one of the Alliance members, a licensor can acquire local partners in all major European markets and speed its time to market. (2) 2' - a, = =_ '- 111.1; iiv 2 ~:This concept implies the design of international strategies based on the interplay between the comparative advantages of countries and the competitive advantages of firms (Kogut 1985). Comparative advantage, sometimes referred to as location specific advantage, arises out of the differences across national markets in factor costs. Thus a firm can gain cost or other advantages by configuring its value chain such that its activities are located in those countries that have lowest cost for a particular factor. National differences can also arise in the markets for fum outputs. Some of these differences arise from varying consumer tastes and preferences, as well as different institutional arrangements that affect the output markets (Kochhar and Hitt 1995). Competitive advantage, sometimes referred to as firm-specific advantage, influences the decision of what activities and technologies along the value-added chain, a fum should concentrate its resources in, i.e., the core competence of the firm. Industrialized countries differ with respect to the environmental conditions of their markets for the global pharmaceutical industry. Differences in national economic, regulatory, and market/industry environments can be sources of comparative advantage to industrialized MN Cs. For example, with respect to regulatory environment, firms based in the US have a comparative advantage as they can benefit from the freedom from price controls on pharmaceuticals. PRICEREG was found to be a significant variable affecting both innovation investment as well as the market potential for diffusion. At the same time, APPTIME - time taken by the regulatory agencies to approve a new drug for marketing was found to have little effect on the innovation environment as well as on the market potential 134 for diffusion. Thus companies need be less cautious of national differences with respect to the above regulatory aspect in their strategic location decisions. Population (POP) for example, was found to be a significant determinant of both market size (MKT SIZE) and R&D expenditure (R&DEXPD). Industrialized countries with large populations could be a source of comparative advantage to firms based in those countries. The large populations in the US and UK as compared to countries such as Belgium or Switzerland are definite sources of comparative advantage to pharmaceutical frrrns looking for large markets. (3) mm: In recent years, several experts have studied the effectiveness of alliances in international business and found them to be an important weapon of competitive advantage in the global competitive arena (Hamel, D02 and Prahalad 1989; Harrigan 1987; Ohmae 1989). According to Hamel et al., "it takes so much money to develop new products and to penetrate new markets, that few companies can go it alone in every situation" (p. 133). According to Shan and Hamilton (1991), such international cooperative ventures provide a firm with access to country-specific advantages embedded in its partners. In the opinion of the above researchers, "international cooperative relationships may be viewed as a vehicle to tap into the comparative advantages of countries" (p. 419). In an empirical study of a sample of domestic and international cooperative relationships of Japanese firms in the biotechnology industry, Shan and Hamilton found country-specific advantages to be a significant variable in explaining differences between cooperative relationships with partners of different countries. The case for collaboration is particularly strong in the global pharmaceutical industry in the present environment. The combined effects of patent erosion, new research methodology, competition from generics and a rise in the real costs of R&D are forcing companies into mergers, acquisitions and alliances. The case for mergers and acquisitions 135 is stronger when attention turns to marketing. Larger operating units are a logical way to cut marketing costs and gain access to new buyers. Few drug producers (particularly European ones) have distribution systems in place in both Japan and the United States, the world's two biggest markets. Japanese MNCs have been especially active in taking advantage of country—specific differences in their choice of collaborations. For example, results of the global innovation and diffusion models reveal the effect of national environmental differences on the markets for developing and introducing N CEs. Firms based in these varying national environments have these effects embedded in them to a certain extent and are better able to deal with the environments in which they are located. Japanese firms, by entering into strategic alliances with US and Western European firms manage to get access to registration and development systems in these countries. For example, Takeda, a major Japanese multinational established a joint venture in the United States with Abbott Laboratories to develop and market ethical drugs. Takeda also has ties with firms in Germany, France, and Italy, and funds research at Harvard and Tulane Universities (Business Week 1990). Merck, the US based multinational formed an alliance with Sigma Tau of Italy in 1982 to co-market a number of products in Italy (USIT C 1991). Italy's market is highly nationalistic and foreign firms need to develop a close relationship with governmental agencies to obtain more timely approval and attractive pricing. This can be possible only through marketing alliances with domestic companies. Merck and Sigma Tau have also entered into a research joint venture agreement, with the Italian company seeking to tap into the comparative advantage in research of the US-based company. 6212 WWW As discussed in the Chapter on Results, the analysis of the global innovation model revealed a poor fit with respect to developing country pharmaceutical industries. In 136 addition, several significant differences as well as opposite effects were found between industrialized country group and the developing country group. This result has important implications. Most research done on industrialized country samples generalizes the findings to developing countries since data on developing countries is scarce. The results of this study show that such generalizations cannot be made. The negative and insignificant relationship between INNOVAT and GBLSALES for the D-group implies that innovation is not a significant determinant of global sales for developing country firms and that there may be other sources of competitive advantage that developing country MNCs can employ. Some recommendations with respect to the strategies that such MNCs can employ are discussed using a similar framework as above. (1) Wales: The pharmaceutical industry in the developing countries consists mostly of reproductive firms (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). These firms are mostly locally-owned or subsidiaries of multinationals or joint ventures between indigenous and foreign companies. In several of these countries, the firms do no more than produce the finished product from imported inputs. However, there are certain core competencies that developing country firms can develop in order to compete in the global market place. The example of Indian pharmaceutical firms is illustrative. Like many other developing countries, India recognizes patents only for processes. Some of its companies specialize in W yielding drugs that are identical to those produced (at much greater expense) by multinationals. The Indian firms begin by selling their new products domestically; later they scale up operations to cut manufacturing costs. The foreign markets which they select as targets are countries that recognize process patents but not patents on the product itself. By the time the companies are ready to export, they can often sell the drugs at less than a tenth the price charged by 137 competitors in industrialized countries (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992; Narayana 1984). The growth of generic markets and the many drugs which will soon come off patent mean that a greater portion of the world's markets could soon be open to producers in developing countries. Some of the newly industrializing countries such as Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan are aggressively targeting the biotechnology market for the future (Howe 1992; 1993). These countries have created technology centers, offered tax incentives, and tried to improve basic science research in order to develop more competent scientists. Korea has been able to compete on high-volume, low-cost products throughout the Southeast Asian region. . : Developing countries differ significantly among themselves with respect to their national economic, regulatory and market/industry environments for pharmaceuticals. That is, countries differ with respect to their comparative advantages. As explained previously, such differences can be exploited for purposes of gaining competitive advantage by multinational firms. For example, Hong Kong is looking into developing a partnership with China, offering its business skills and tapping China's scientific expertise, low wages and plentiful natural resources. The Hong Kong Institute of Biotechnology has partnered with the Chinese Academy of Sciences to identify marketable compounds from traditional Chinese remedies (Howe 1993). Hong Kong may then use the expertise it gains to launch its own industry and as a result become competitive in the future. Third World MNCs can take advantage of the booming economies of the NICs and their growing markets for pharmaceuticals. For example, Singapore has attracted new material production, formulation and packaging plants because of the attractive incentives 138 offered by the Singapore government. Singapore is poised to become the medical treatment and distribution center for the Southeast Asian region. (3) Waste: For developing country MNCs, competing via participation in joint ventures or alliances is a particularly useful mode for entering the global market. Since most firms from such countries are small with insufficient research and production resources, collaboration can provide the means to pool resources and acquire access to new markets. Most Western pharmaceutical companies for example, choose to enter developing country markets through joint ventures. Developing country firms can gain important technological know-how from the more advanced multinationals in return for their marketing expertise and familiarity with local governmental agencies. China for example, is establishing growing links with fnms from industrialized country who are interested in developing retail and OTC products from traditional Chinese herbal remedies. Some foreign participants hope to make use of Chinese research on biological agents which they could convert into drugs. Other arrangements call for Chinese scientists to conduct the research and the collaborator to develop the products. Later the Chinese are expected to test the prototypes in research facilities provided by their overseas partner (Ballance, Pogany and Forstner 1992). 62-2 W The pharmaceutical industry is unique in that it is one of the few industries in which, in almost all countries, the government plays an important role and takes a keen interest in industry operations. Because the industry is of such social importance, the government sees itself as a major regulating force and acts by formulating a variety of policies affecting the industry in critical ways. 139 6.2.2.1 ’c ' I i ti r 'liz un ri The results of the study reveal that a country's economic, regulatory and market/industry environment have a significant impact on the factors that directly affect global competitiveness. Further, the above environments are also found to exert significant indirect effects on global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. With respect to the economic environment, GNP was found to be a significant variable affecting market size, industry focus and industry concentration. It was also found to impact investment in innovation. Thus industrialized country governments need to evaluate the nation's economic environment before taking policy measures with respect to the pharmaceutical industry. A robust economy seems necessary for a thriving industry. Population size was also a significant factor affecting both market size and industry focus. The large industrialized countries with significant populations should take advantage of this in promoting the pharmaceutical industry further. With respect to the regulatory environment, price control was the only significant factor affecting competitiveness. It had a significant negative effect on market size and R&D investment for innovation. It also had a significant indirect negative effect on both innovation and global sales. Further it also had a significant negative impact on the market potential for diffusion of new drugs. Industrialized countries need to develop creative means of price control such that incentives for industrial innovation are not affected and health care is accessible to all at the same time. UK is one country that has been successful in this attempt. It uses a program called PPRS. This is a voluntary program and is intended to maintain price levels that allow for a "reasonable return on capital," to ensure that prices of pharmaceutical products are not raised arbitrarily, and to limit the cost of drugs to the National Health Service 140 (N HS). The PPRS is credited with having increased investment in the British pharmaceutical industry (Taggart 1993). In contrast, the price control program used in Germany is expected to negatively impact innovation in the future. The program utilizes the concept of therapeutic clustering, and has reportedly resulted in a 25-40 percent decrease in pharmaceutical prices in Germany. Therapeutic clustering, or the grouping of drug products for similar indications for reimbursement at similar price levels by either health insurance plans or national health systems, regardless of whether the products are patent protected, is expected to exacerbate the impact of cost-containment efforts. Pricing controls have also been enacted in almost all of the EC countries. The implementation of price controls in the EC has resulted in price differentiation in the individual countries, which has, in turn, resulted in increased parallel trade. The undercutting in price that results from parallel trade results in decrease in revenue, which could in turn have a potentially negative impact on R&D. With respect to market/industry environment, market size was the most important factor affecting R&D expenditures as well as outbound foreign investment. A large home market size promoted greater investment in innovation and had a significant indirect effect on global competitiveness. Thus industrialized country governments need to maintain market demand in the home country by implementing appropriate policies that have the effect of increasing pharmaceutical market size. One of the means by which this can be achieved has already been discussed, namely restrict policies that implement stringent price controls. Innovation investment or R&D expenditure had a direct effect on global innovation (number of NCEs developed) which in turn was a strong explanatory variable of global sales (global competitiveness). Policies in industrialized countries should therefore be geared to increase industrial investment in innovation. National funding agencies such as the NIH in the US have been important sources of R&D funding for the industry. Japan 141 reportedly has 19 different tax incentive systems to encourage technological innovation, including an R&D tax credit similar to that of the United States. Federal government support for medical research in the US continues to exceed funds allocated by other national governments (USI'I'C 1991). Global innovation was also the most important determinant of global diffusion. This implies that factors that encourage global innovation will also encourage global diffusion. To be frequent first-time recipients of new drug discoveries (NCEs) is obviously an important social goal for all industrialized countries. Introduction of NCEs into the market also has the effect of increasing industry competition and thus driving innovation. Thus all of the above policy issues relevant for industrial innovation are also relevant for increasing diffusion of NCEs into the country. In sum, public policies in industrialized country markets must be geared towards increasing GNP, increasing market demand for pharmaceuticals, restricting price control measures and increasing investment in R&D in order to promote global competitiveness of its pharmaceutical industry. 6.2.2.2 l’ P 'c Im i i D v I r As discussed earlier, policies that work for industrialized countries are assumed to be universally applicable for all developing and under-developed countries in order to achieve the same level of economic development. Lall (1990) advisor to the OECD, is of the view that such conventional approaches lead to wrong policy responses. For example, the World Bank's structural adjustment policy recommendations for industry in developing countries have little directly to say about the time lag between policy changes and supply response, human resource development or the needs of institution building. They barely differentiate among countries' different levels of development. 142 In most studies related to technology and economic growth, "technology" is taken to be freely available to all countries and, within countries, to all firms. To the extent that technology lags are admitted, developing countries are taken to receive all relevant improvements from developed country innovators; there is no problem in assimilating the transferred technology; there are no adaptations required, etc. The results of this study show that the causal variables for global competitive advantage in the pharmaceutical industry not only have opposite effects for developing country industries but also that these effects overall may not be significant in being able to explain the determinants of competitiveness. This has significant implications for public policy makers and consultants to the pharmaceutical industry in developing countries. Policy makers in developing countries need to focus on the following aspects to improve the position of the firms both nationally and internationally. (1) Improve and strengthen the scientific base for development and production of the traditional medicine and household remedies. (2) Invest in development of repackaging and formulation plants. (3) Advance development and production of bulk drugs, including immunologicals and antibiotics. (4) Establish regulations relating to domestic and foreign corporate ventures and the importation of foreign drugs, intermediates and know-how. (5) Review pricing and patent protection policies for increasing market attractiveness for foreign investment. (6) Promote exports of pharmaceutical preparations and encourage international collaborations with both developing and developed country firms. Public policy makers are often guilty of being too enamored of the gadgetry and high technology, thus distorting the pattern of investment in health care supplies and pharmaceuticals. Governments in these countries need to appreciate that they cannot achieve quickly the same level of sophisticated technology as the United States or Japan. They will have to make the best use of what is currently available, because advanced innovation is beyond their means or not as important as other needs atleast for now. 143 6.3 TRIB T N F HE 6.3.1 IhecretieaLflontribLticus The present study makes significant theoretical contributions to several streams of literature, namely the literature on national competitiveness; literature on pharmaceutical innovation and diffusion; the economic development literature; and the global strategic management literature. With respect to the national competitiveness literature, it tests theoretical concepts in the Theory of Comparative Advantage, the Technology Factor theory; Porter's theory of the National Diamond of Competitiveness; and the role of government in national competitiveness. Comparative advantages of countries with respect to their economic, regulatory and market/industry environments are found to be important for competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry. Technology - ability to innovate is found to be a significant factor in global competitive advantage for the pharmaceutical industry. Both factor and demand conditions in Porter's diamond of national competitive advantage were tested empirically with regards to the pharmaceutical industry and found significant. The debate on the role of government in national competitiveness was tested in this study with respect to a single industry. The regulatory factors were found to significantly affect the determinants of competitiveness. With respect to the theoretical literature on pharmaceutical innovation and diffusion; it makes a contribution by considering factors beyond just the effect of regulatory variables that most studies in the above literature have examined. This study tests a comprehensive 144 model considering a variety of supply and demand factors affecting pharmaceutical innovation and diffusion. The contributions of this study to the theories on economic development are also important. By empirically testing the same model for both industrialized and developing countries, the results show that determinants of competitive advantage vary significantly for the two groups. The results refute the generalized assumption of the Technology factor theory that developing countries can simply imitate the developed country model of technology and increase their rate of economic growth. The study results also provide interesting insights for the global strategic management literature. Most importantly, the study points to the importance of national environments and the need for firms to be able to adapt to varying economic, regulatory, and industry environments to be competitive. Most global strategic management research has tended to focus on factors endogenous to the firm and ignored the more macro factors affecting frrrn competitiveness in the global economy (Bolton and Boyacigiller 1993). 6.3.2 Empiricalfirmtrjhuticns The present study makes significant empirical contributions to the global competitiveness literature on the pharmaceutical industry. According to the US International Trade Commission report (USITC 1991), most studies in the above literature have focused on US firms, using mono-national samples or bi-national samples at the most. There are just a handful of studies using several country samples focusing on overall factors affecting all countries taken together, not just one country. A second shortcoming in the research on global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry is that most studies have considered only regulatory factors in exclusion to additional factors which are as important if not more. 145 A third weakness in previous research on global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry, identified by USITC, is the primary focus on supply related factors of innovation. Demand related factors have been ignored, i.e., factors affecting demand for pharmaceutical innovations across national markets, which are of great strategic importance. A fourth shortcoming in the research on global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry is the predominant focus on the industrialized countries. Admittedly, it is the industrialized country firms that play a major role in the global competition in pharmaceuticals, however one cannot forget the enormous social importance of the industry and its role in improving quality of life for all humans. Competitiveness issues with respect to the developing countries' pharmaceutical industry deserve more attention and research. The present study attempts to overcome the above limitations as follows: (1) The study utilizes a sample of over 200 firms representing twenty-seven countries which is far more than the USITC study which used twenty-nine firms representing seven countries for assessing competitiveness. (2) The study examines the effect of several variables in addition to regulatory variables, such as GNP, population size, market size, industry focus, industry concentration, industry growth, foreign investment, foreign commitment, etc., on pharmaceutical innovation. (3) The study examines both supply related and demand related factors affecting global competitiveness in the pharmaceutical industry as recommended in the USITC report. (4) The study examines both industrialized countries and developing countries, finding significant differences between the two, with crucial managerial and public policy implications for developing countries emerging as a result of the analysis. 6.3.3 It i t' This study uses structural equation modeling (SEM) to test the path diagrams developed from the theoretical literature. SEM is an extension of several multivariate techniques and provides a means of dealing with multiple dependence relationships 146 simultaneously while providing statistical efficiency (Hayduk 1987). To the best of this researcher's knowledge, there are no studies using the above statistical method in the research on pharmaceutical innovation and diffusion. The few empirical studies in this area use regression techniques at the most. 63.4 W The results of this study make significant contributions with respect to the managerial and public policy literature. These have been discussed previously in section 6.2. 64 W The major limitation is with respect to the nature of international data used in the study. Differences in accounting terms and techniques exist. The definition of pharmaceutical business is also notoriously varied. Shifts in exchange rates have affected performance; for example in recent years the Europeans and Japanese have particularly benefited from the depreciation of the dollar. Therefore, some of the data may not be capable of direct comparison. However, maximum effort has been made where ever possible to correct for inconsistencies and ensure the comparability of the data used in this study. A second limitation is with respect to the time frame used in the study. Data over a four year period (1990 to 1994) was used. Resource constraints with respect to time available to the researcher for collecting and inputting the data in a usable form prevented use of a longer time frame for the study. However, this is not considered as a major limitation but may in fact have been the appropriate time frame to use. This is because a longer time frame would have introduced confounding effects due to the significant changes in the global environment of the pharmaceutical industry taking place in the late 147 19805. Availability of a longer time frame would have necessitated splitting the analysis into two time periods to weed out the confounding effects. It would of course be interesting to do a two period analysis to observe differences if any with respect to the effect of the various factors tested. A third limitation of the study is that it focuses on a single industry - the pharmaceutical industry. Results may not be generalizable to other industries. However, the path models and the variables tested are general enough to be applied to other industries as well. Thus, future research could be done for other industries as well. Finally, a greater number of regulatory variables need to be tested with respect to their effect on innovation and diffusion of NCEs. Difference between countries with respect to their product liability laws, patent protection legislation, licensing and joint- venture policies, etc. have important effects on rate of inter country innovation and diffusion of NCEs. Inclusion of each additional variable to the models used in this study would have greatly increased the complexity of the research design and rendered interpretation of the results difficult. 6.5 W Some suggestions for future research have been discussed in the section on study limitations. Other suggestions are discussed below. The global pharmaceutical industry has been undergoing increasing international consolidation in the past decade. The consolidation has ranged from mergers to strategic alliances. Such corporate strategies have changed the structure of the global industry with respect to industry concentration and definition of national corporate identity. It has also obviously affected the nature of competition in the industry. Greater empirical and theoretical research on the above issue is needed to extend the state of knowledge on competitiveness in the global pharmaceutical industry. 148 A second area of research closely related to pharmaceuticals is the area of biotechnology. According to the USITC study, biopharrnaceuticals are expected to account for an increasing share of pharmaceutical production within the next decade. Several countries, especially Japan have identified biotechnology as the most important industry for competitiveness in the future (Tokyo Business Today 1990). The Japanese biotechnology industry is reportedly in a position to become a major competitor in the world market. Thus, the role of the biotechnology industry in the global competitiveness of a country's pharmaceutical industry needs to be researched. LIST OF REFERENCES 149 LIST OF REFERENCES Adams, I. and L. Klein (eds. ) (1982), Industrial Eelicies fer Growth and Commtitiveness: W Heath: D C Agrawal, Madhu (1993), "International Pharmaceutical Marketing: An Historical Perspective," Eteceedings of the Siuth Ceuference an Histetleal Reseaueh in Marketing aud Matketln ng IIIheught, Jeffrey B. Schmidt, Stanley C. Hollander, Terence Nevett and Jagdish N. Sheth (eds), Michigan State University, 363- 376. Ballance, Robert, Janos Pogany and Helrnut Forstner (1992), The Werld's Eh maeeutieal e ntem ion Pers iv 11 Innovati n om i0 and li , Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd: England. Bogner, William C. and Howard Thomas (1992), Core Competence and Competitive Advantage: A Mgel and Illustrative Evideng from the Phguaceutical Indusuy, WP 4900, no-92-0174, Bureau of Economic and Business Research: University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. Bolton, Michele K. and Nakiye A. Boyacigiller (1993), "A Model for Comparative Research on New Product Introductions," Advauces in International Comparative Management, 8, 217-240. Brownlee, Oswald H. (1979),"The Economic Consequences of Regulating without Regard to Economic Consequences," in Issues in Pharmaceutical Ecenomics, Robert I. Chien (ed.), Lexington, Mass: D.C. Heath, 215-228. Business Week (1990), "Japan's Next Battleground: The Medicine Chest," (March 12), 68. Carre, J.J., P. Dubois, and E. Malinvaud (1975), Ereueh Eeenetuie Qruwth, Stanford University Press: Stanford, CA. Caves, Richard 15., Michael D. Whinston and Mark A. Hurwitz (1991), "Patent Expiration, Entry, and Competition in the US Pharmaceutical Industry," Breokings Papers; thmcoaornics 1-66 Chemical Engineering News (1961), "Britain's Drug Makers Under Fire," 39 (March 6), 92-93. Chemical Marketing Reporter (1991), "Drug Producers in US. Find Overseas Rivals a Challenge," 240 (July 29) 7-8. (1992a), "Pharmaceuticals '92: Legislative Incisions," 241: 10 (March 9), SR6—SR8. (1992b), "Pharmaceuticals '92: To Cap or not to Cap," 241: 10 (March 9), SR3- SR4. 150 Cheuueaflljeeh (1991), "Pharmaceuticals: Pressure on Prices and Profits," 149:2 (August 7), 26-31. Clymer, Harold A. (1970), "The Changing Costs of Pharmaceutical Innovation," Ermeediugs ef the First Settling en Ecenemics ef Phar_r_naceutical Innovatieu, Joseph D. Cooper (ed) The American University, Washington, D. C.,109-124. (1975), "The Economic and Regulatory Climate: US and Overseas Trends," in Drug Development and Maketing, Robert B. Helms (ed.), American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, DC, 137-154. Cohen, S, D. Teece, L. Tyson and J. Zysman (1984), "Global Competition, The New Reality," Wethlug papet at the Etesident's Cammissiea ea ludusttial Commtiu'veness, University of California, Berkeley, CA. Comanor, WS (1986), "The Political Economy of the Pharmaceutical Industry," luumal margarine, 24 (Sept). 1178-1217. Commission on Industrial Competitiveness (1985), Glehal Cemmtiu'eh; flfhe New Reality. Cooper, Joseph D. (ed. ) (1969), "The Economics of Drug Innovation," in Pr e W Joseph D (Snooper (ed. ), The American University, Washington, D. C. (1976), "Regulation, Economics and Pharmaceutical Innovation," in W ' minar 11 Economics of Ph aceu ical In v ion, Joseph D. Cooper (ed.), The American University, Washington, DC. Cornwall, J. (1976), "Diffusion, Convergence and Kaldor's Law," Economic Jeumal, 85: 307-3 14. Council on Competitiveness (1991), A Cempetitive Prefile uf the Bugs and maageuttealhtdustty, Washington, DC: Council on Competitiveness. Davis, Lester A. (1991), "Technology Intensity of US, Canadian, and Japanese Manufactures Output and Exports," in Tec and Na i nal C m et' ’v ° Oligepely, flfechnologieal Innevatien, and lutetuational Cempetition, Jorge Niosi (ed.), McGill-Queens Univ. Press: Montreal. Dension, ER (1967), Why Grewth Rates Differ; Best-war Exmrieuee iu Nine Westetu thutu'es, Brookings Institute, Washington, DC. DiMasi, Joseph, Ronald Hansen, Henry Grabowski, and Louis Lasagna (1991), "The Cost of Innovation in the Pharmaceutical Industry," 1911 mal ef Health Eeeneuties, 10:2,107-42. Dixit, A. (1986), "Trade Policy: An Agenda for Research," in Suateglejtadel’uhemd WWW P.Krugman (ed.). MIT Press. Dosi, Giovanni and Luc Soete (1991), "Technological Innovation and International Competitiveness," in T n 1 an Nat' l m itive e55' li ol lfgflolegieal Innovation, and International Competition, Jorge Niosi (ed.), McGill- Queens Univ. Press: Montreal. 151 Dunning, John H. (1988), "International Direct Investment in Innovation: The Pharmaceutical Industry," in M ltin ' n 1 lo 11 cm e i 'v n Unwin Hyman: London, 123-141. Ihflgpuuuu'st (1986), "Drugs in Asia: Opening a New Medicine Chest," 299 (May 31) 299. flfhe Economist (1988), "Selling to Japan, Drug on the Market," 309 (Dec 10) 70. The Eeunemist (1989), "The New World of Drugs," Feb. 4, p. 63. Ernst, Dieter and David O'Connor (1989), Technelegy aud G1 ehal Compet ltlen; flfh e Challen nge fer rNewly Industrigiging gaueudes, OECD, France. W (1989), "Pharmaceutical Pricing: A Cause for French Concern," Mar. 20, p. 20. Fagerberg, Jan (1987), "A Technology Gap Approach to Why Growth Rates Differ," 1n The Ecenemics at ln_nevatier_t, Christopher Freeman (ed.), Edward Elgar Pub. Ltd.: England, 55-67. Fenton, RC. (1963), "Worldwide Ethical Drug Markets," WM, 93 (November), 624. Financial Wetld (1989), "Pharmaceuticals," 158 (May 30), 53 - 80. Franko, Lawrence G. (1987), "Global Competitive Performance and the Geographic Location of Corporate Activity," presented at the S ' ' Cenference, Boston. (1989), "Global Corporate Competition: Who's Winning, Who's Losing, and the R&D Factor as One Reason Why," tr te ic M emen urn , 10, 449-474. Geringer, Michael J. and Paul W. Beamish (1989), "Diversification Strategy and Internationalization: Implications for MNE Performance," Strategic Management leumal, 10, 109-119. Ghoshal, Sumantra (1987), "Global Strategy: An Organizing Framework," Sttategle WM. 8:5. 425-140. Goldstein, J. and S. Krasner (1984), "Unfair Trade Practices: The Case for a Differential Response," Amer-1W. 74:2. Gomulka, S. (1971), "Inventive Activity, Diffusion and Stages of Economic Growth, " Wm 24 Aarhus Grabowski, Henry G. (1976), "Structural Effects of Regulation in the Ethical Drug Industry,"in| .-. 1n !! tov or E _iri Evir - n39 thlous, American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington D. C., 55- 63. (1980), "Regulation and the International Diffusion of Pharmaceuticals," in The lntemational Supply ef Medicines, Robert B. Helms (ed.), American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D.C. 152 ___(1989), "An Analysis of US International Competitiveness in Pharmaceuticals, Mmagen rim and mcisien Egenemics, Special Issue, 27- 33. (1990), "Innovation and International Competitiveness in Pharmaceuticals," The Proce in f the 2nd Intern ion 05 Sc et ie M e in Arbor, MI: University of Michigan, pp. 167-185. and John M. Vernon (1976),"Structura1 Effects of Regulation on Innovation in the Ethical Drug Industry," in R. Masson and D. Qualls (eds.), Essa s ' thanihatmn in honor of Joe Bain, Cambridge, Mass: Ballinger. ___dan _(1977), "Consumer Protection Regulation in Ethical Drugs," American gen ne—fl'e Review, 67(Feb), 359- 364. , and Lacy Glen Thomas (1978), "Estimating the Effects of Regulation on Innovation: An International Comparative Analysis of the Pharmaceutical Industry," leumal at Law and Econumies, 21 (1), Spring, pp. 133-163. Grant, Robert M. ( 1987), "Multinationality and Performance among British Manufacturing Companies," Jamal pf International Business Stum'es, 18:3, 79-89. Hamel, Gary, Yves L. Doz and CK. Prahalad (1989), "Collaborate with your Competitors and Win," Hmard Business Review, (Jan/Feb), 133-139. Hansen, R (1979), "The Pharmaceutical Development Process. Estimates of Development Costs and Times and the Effects of Proposed Regulatory Changes," in R. Chien (ed) WW Lexington Mass: Lexington Books Harberger, A.C. (ed.) (1984), mm, ICS Press, San Francisco, CA. Harrigan, Kathryn Rudie (1987), "Strategic Alliances: Their New Role in Global Competition," 01 m i W r1 'n s , (Summer), 67-69. Hatsopoulos, G., P. Krugman and L. Summers (1988), "US Competitiveness: Beyond the Trade Deficit," Seieum, (July 15). Hatzichronoglou, Thomas (1991) "Indicators of Industrial Competitiveness. Results and Limitations, " in T 1i. ~ 1 - hn Morse Niosi (ed) McGill- Queens Univ Press. Montreal. Hauptman, Oscar and Edward B. Roberts (1987), "FDA Regulation of Product Risk and its Impact Upon Young Biomedical Firms," u r I Management, 4:2 (June), 138-148. Hayduk, Leslie A. (1987), Stmeuualflu ' n o ' w' i r ° Ess ni Adyanees, John Hopkins University Press: Baltimore. Howe, David C. (1992), "Pharmaceuticals in Southeast Asia: Markets, Production and Competitors: Part I," EastAsianEmuu'yeRepmts, 14: 11 (Nov 15), 8, 22-25. ___(1993), " "Pharmaceuticals in Southeast Asia: Markets, Production and Competitors: Part II,"East_Asran_Exr&_ut1£Remns 15: 1 (Jan 15). 8, 24+. Ker Kot K0 Kr La 153 Huber, P. (1988). W. New York. Hymer, S. H. (1960), The Intemational Dnerations ef Natienal Firms; A Study ef Di 1th Wm, Ph. D. Dissertation, MIT. ITA (International Trade Administration) (1984), A Qampetitive Assessment of the ES mmeetmealjndusm, Washington, D. C.: U. S. Department of Commerce. J affe Marvin E. f(1976), "Drug ReguDlatory Patterns Worldwide: Trends and Realities," in Impaet ef Euhlie Peliey en Dmg Innevatiun and Prieing, S. A. Mitchell and E. A. Link (eds. ), The American University: Washington, D. C., 277- 287. Jaffe, Thomas (1983), "Drugs," Forhes, 131 (Jan 3), 192-193. James, Barrie G. (1983), "International Marketing," in 'nci 1e f P Mageting," 3rd. Ed., Mickey C. Smith (ed.), Lea and Febiger: Philadelphia. Ihelapanl’unes (1990), "Japan Patents Wrapped in Red Tape," Aug. 27, p. 20. Jarrell, S. (1983), "Research and Development and Firm Size in the Pharmaceutical Industry," Business ficnomics, (Sept), 26-39. Johnson, C. (ed.) (1984), The lndustrial Policy Dehate, Institute for Contemporary Studies. Kamien, Morton I. and Nancy L. Schwartz (1970), "Market Structure, Elasticity of Demand and the Incentive to Invest," MW. 13:1. _(1982). W. Cambridge University Press. Keller, B. G, and Smith, Mickey C. (1969), Eh mmaeeutical Marketing, An Anthelegy and Ejhlrpgtaphy. Baltimore: The Williams and Wilkins Co. Kennedy, PM. (1987), 11‘ ' e 1.!' - o 1' -, .‘owr- ,ono _...t°- .. d W Random House. New York. Kochhar, Rahul and Michael A. Hitt (1995), "Toward an Integrative Model of International Diversification " WW 1:1 33- 72 Kogut, Bruce (1985), "Designing Global Strategies: Comparative and Competitive Value- Addcd Chains." WW. (Summer). 15-28. Kremers, Edward and Urdang, George (1940), Histei'y at Ehannaey; A Guide and a Stuyey. Philadelphia, London, and Montreal: J.B. Lippincott Co. Lall, Sanjaya (1985), "Appropriate Pharmaceutical Policies in Developing Countries," Managerialandflrcisionfimnucs (1990), 'es, OECD: Paris. Landau, R. (1990), "Capital Investment: Key to Competitiveness and Growth, " _T_he Bmkrrrgsmifl/ Summer 154 Lasagna, Louis (1969), "Constraints on the Innovation of Drugs," in Prmgmdin ngs at the WWW Joseph D Cooper (ed. ). The American University, Washington, D. C. ___(1989),"Congress, the FDA. and New Drug Development: Before and After 1962," 've in iol (1 Medicine, 32: (3), Spring. (1991), "The Chilling Effect of Product Liability on New Drug Development," in The Liability Maze, Peter W. Huber and Robert E. Litan (eds.), Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 334-359. and William M. Wardell (1975), "The Rate of New Drug Discovery," in Drug Deuelepmenhanddtlmketimg, Robert B. Helms (ed.), American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D.C., 137-154. Leonard, W.N. (1971), "Research and Development in Industrial Growth," Immalpi Wary, 79:2 (March/April), 232-256. Longman, Roger (1994), "Joint Marketing in Europe," Ph ti al tr i ' s, 4th ed., Windhover Information Inc.: N orwalk, CT. Loury, GO (1979), "Market Structure and Innovation," Qumterly leumal ef Econemies, August. M i M ti (1990), "Japan: The Pharmaceutical Market here is the World's 2nd Largest," Aug. pp. 22-34. Magaziner, I. and R. Reich (1982), Minding Amen’ea's Business, HBJ. Mansfield, E. (1968), Industrial Researeh and Technelogieal Innevatien, W.W. Norton: New York. M i A v isin New lett (1990), Sept 15, 4-5. Merck and Co. (1988), Health Dare Innovation; The Case for a Favorable Public Pulicy, p. 23. Mitchell 8 A deA Link (cds ) (1976) new andEfieing, The American University: Washington, D. C. Moskowitz, M. (1961), "Drugs, the International Explosion." Dmg and Qosmetic Industm- 88 (Jan). 42. NAB (1983), The Dom mpetiti ve Stams of the D. S, Eh annaceutical Indus shy: The Influences 0 ‘ 1100 t D m 1' H .1: o - iiv AMV -. ,Washington, D. C.: National Academy Press. Narayana, PL. (1984), The Indian Ehannaeeutieal lndustm; Problems and Presimets, NCAER: New Delhi, India. Niosi, Jorge(1991), l N i 'ivene : 1i 1 Technl l lnnevatien, and Intematienal Qammtitien, Jorge Niosi (ed.), McGill-Queens Univ. Press: Montreal. 155 and Philippe Faucher (1991), "The State and International Trade: Technology and __CompetitivchSS" in W W 119-141 Ohmae, Kenichi (1989), "The Global Logic of Strategic Alliances," i es Review, (March/April), 143-154. Parker, J.B.S. (1984), The lntematiunal Diffusian af thaeeutieals, New York: St. Martin's Press. Peltzman, Sam (1973), "An Evaluation of Consumer Protection Legislation: The 1962 Drug Amendments," ,lomal of Ealitieal Eeenemy, 81 (Sep/Oct), 1049-1091. ,.J DiRaddo and A. Fringeri (1980), "A Preliminary Analysis of the Rate of Development of New Drugs by British- owned Pharmaceutical Firms," in Emeedings of a Symtmsium an nEu’sk md Eegulau'en, London: Trust for Education and Research 1n Therapeutics. M. May and G. Trimble (1982), "New Drug Development by United States Pharmaceutical Firms " WW 32 407-417 Phillips, A. (1956), "Concentration, Scale and Technological Change in Selected Manufacturing Industries, 1899- 1939, " JuumaLeLMstnaljeenomum, June. PMA (1989). BMW. P- 7- (1990), Better Healdi Tmough New Medieines and an Impreved FDA, Statement to the Subcommittee on Drugs and Biologics of the Advisory Committee on the Food and Drug Administration, Department of Health and Human Services, Sept. 13, pp' 1’5. Popper, Kathleen M. LaFrancis and Robert W. N ason (1994), "The Drug Lag: A 20-year. Analysis of Six Country Markets," leumal ef Dahlia Pelicy and Marketing, 13:2 (Fall), 290-299. Porter, Michael E. (1990), The Qummu'tive Advantage ef Natiens, New York: Free Press. Posner, M.V. (1961), "International Trade and Technical Change," MM Ramps, 13: 323-341. Pradhan, Suresh B. (1983), Intematienal Phatmaeeutieal Marketing, Quorum Books: Westport, Connecticut. Prahalad, C. K. and Gary Hamel (1990), "The Core Competence of the Corporation," WW (May-June) 79- 91 Redwood, Heinz (1988), The Prha rcma eu tieal lndusti‘y- Tten ds, Er reb lems and _ehieyements, Oldwicks Press Ltd.: England. (1991), "Pharmaceuticals: The Price/Research Spiral," LungEangeElaLning, 24:2 (April), 16-27. Reich, R. (1983), "Beyond Free Trade," Eereign Affairs, 61:4. 156 Robinson, Richardson D. (1991), "Toward Creating an International Technology Transfer Paradigm" in n rn i m ni tion f T h 010 B0 Reath'ngs, ed. Richard D. Robinson, Taylor and Francis: New York. Rothwell, Roy and Walter Zegveld (1981), "Government Regulations and Innovation," lndusm'al lnnevation md bblic Policy; Preparing for the 12805 and the 122015n Greenwood Press: Westport, Connecticut. Rugman, Alan(l985), "National Strategies for International Competitiveness," Mulu'natienal Business, (3), 1-9. Sarett, Lewis H. (1974), "FDA Regulations and Their Influence on Future R&D," RmamhManascmcnt. 27 (March). 18-20. Schankerman, Mark (1976), "Common Costs in Pharmaceutical Research and Development: Implications for Direct Price Regulation," in lmpaet ef Puhlie Peliey en mg Innevatien and Prieing, S.A. Mitchell and EA. Link (eds.), The American University: Washington, D.C. Scherer, F. M. (1976), "Corporate Inventive Output, Profits and Growth," loumal of thncalflcnornx 73=.3(DCC)101-111 Schumpeter, J. (1934), The Theeiy ef Ecanomie Develepment, Oxford. Schwartzman. David (1976). WWW. John Hopkins Univ. Press: Baltimore. Scott, RS. and G.C. Lodge (1985), U. om iiv nes in h W r1 Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA. Serip (1990), "Prospects for 'Bungyo' in Japan," Apr. 27, p. 26. W (1989), PJB Pubs. Ltd.: Richmond, England. Serip Maga_zine (1994), "Single-digit growth for World Pharmaceutical Market," PJB Pubs. Ltd.: Richmond, England. Sen’p Review (1990), PJB Pubs. Ltd.: Richmond, England. (1991), PJB Pubs. Ltd.: Richmond, England. Shan, Weijian and William Hamilton (1991), "Country-specific Advantage and International Cooperation," Suategie Management leumal, 12: 419-432. Smith, Mickey C.(1983), Er_i_neip_les_e_f_Phatmaeeutieal_Marketing. 3rd Ed., edited by Mickey C. Smith, Philadelphia: Lea and Febiger. __ (1991). WWW. Haworth Press: New York. Spilker, Bert (1989), ' 1 a1 i : sues in Di c ve W211i. New York: Raven Press. 157 Swazey, Judith P. (1991), "Prescription Drug Safety and Product Liability," in The W, Peter W. Huber and Robert E. Litan (eds.,) Washington, D. C: The Brookings Institution, 291- 333. Steward, HF. (1977), "Public Policy and Innovation in the Drug Industry," in Emyiding tor Realth Serviees, Sir Douglas Black and GP. Thomas (eds.), Croom Helm: London. Taggart, James H. (1993), The Wetld Eharmageuticm lndusuy, RoutledgezLondon. Takada, Hirokazu and Dipak Jain (1991), "Cross-National Analysis of Diffusion of Consumer Durable Goods in Pacific Rim Countries," leumal pf Marketing, 55 (April), 48-54. Tenrin, Peter (1979), "Technology, Regulation, and Market Structure in the Modern Pharmaceutical Industry," Bell Jeumal of Eenemics, 10 (Autumn), 427-446. Temple, Peter. (1991), "Tougher Times Ahead for a Global Market." Aceountaney. 107 (Feb) 88 -89. Thomas, Howard and Robert M. Grant (1987), "Is Diversification Profitable?," presented at Suategie Management Socieni Denfemnce, Boston. Thomas, Lacy G. (1989), "Spare the Rod and Spoil the Industry: Vigorous Competition and Vigorous Regulation Promote Global Competitive Advantages," unpulaliLhed, October. (1990),"Regulation and Firm Size: FDA Impacts on Innovation," Rand leumal af Eeenemies, 21:4 (Winter), 497-517. Thorelli, Hans B. (1990), "International Marketing: An Ecologic View," in lntematienal Marketing Strategy, 3rd. ed., eds. Hans B. Thorelli and S. Tamer Cavusgil, New York: Pergamon Press. To B ' T (1988), "No Magic Pill for Pharmaceutical Makers," (June), 34- 38. (1990), "Japanese Pharmaceutical Makers are Globalizing Operations, " (June) 34- 35. Toyne, Brian and Peter G. P. Walters (1993), "Global Business Operations: Patterns and Theories," in Q1 ehal Mmketing Management; A Str riateg e Eer rspeetive, 2nd ed., Boston: Allyn and Bacon. Tyson, L. (1990), "Managed Trade: Making the Best of Second Best, " in An Amenea_n Trade Sttategy; Optiens fat the l22lls, R. Lawrence and C. Shultze (eds.,) Brookings. U. S. Department of Commerce (1989), D. S. Direct Investment Abroad: Dperations of WW July 1989 USITC (1990), "Japan' 5 Distribution System and Options for Improving U. S. Access", W Oct... P 2 11 158 USITC (1991), lob cm i 'veness f . van - l M f Industties: Eharmaceutieals, United States International Trade Commission, Washington, DC 20436. U.S. Industrial Outlook (1991), Dmgs, p. 45-2. Villard, H.H. (1958), "Competition, Oligopoly and Research," f P l' ' 1 My, December. Wachter, M and S. Wachter (eds) (1982), Teward a New DS Industrial Eeliey, University of Pennsylvanra. Wardell, William M. (1973), "Introduction of New Therapeutic Drugs in the US and Great Britain. An International Comparison," WM, 14: 5 (Sept- Oc-t), 773- 790. (1974), "Therapeutic Implications of the Drug Lag," 1i i l P 010 Theramuties, 15:1 (Jan), 73-96. (1975), "Developments in the Introduction of New Drugs in the United States and Great Britain, 1971-1974," in Dru v 1 men Mark ' , Robert B. Helms (ed.), American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research, Washington, D.C., 165- 182. and Lorraine E. Sheck (1982), "Is Pharmaceutical Innovation Declining?: Interpreting Measures of Pharmaceutical Innovation and Regulatory Impact in the USA, 1950-1980," in Eharmaceutieal Eeenemics, ed. Bjorn Lindgren, Swedish Institute for Health Economics: Stockholm, 177-189. Wiggins, Steven N. (1981), "Product Quality Regulation and New Drug Introductions: Some New Evidence from the 19705, " Rev vieyy at flenemies and Statisties, 63: 615- 619. (1983), "The Impact of Regulation on Pharmaceutical Research Expenditures: A Dynamic Approach," Ecenemie Enguity, 21: 115-128. __(,1984) "The Effect of US Pharmaceutical Regulation on New Introductions," EhatmLceutieaLEeqntmiies, ed. Bjorn Lindgren, Swedish Institute for Health Economics: Stockholm, 191 2-05. Wills, James, A. Coskun Samli and Laurence Jacobs (1991), "Developing Global Products and Marketing Strategies: A Construct and Research Agenda, " lmunaLpLdie Woes. 19(1),110. Yoshikawa, Aki (1989), "The Other Drug War: US-Japan Trade in Pharmaceuticals," CaliicntiaManascmLLRmc—W (Winter). 7690 Young, J .H. (1982), Dahlia Pelicy and Drug Innevatien, American Institute of the History of Pharmacy. APPENDIX A 159 APPENDIX A Table A.1 Global Innovation Model . Paths Overall Industrialized Developin v3,v1 0.19021 0.423 -.129 Economic env ---> (0.167)b 0.225 .265 Mkt/Ind structure 1.08 4c 1.725 -.486 V 3, v 2 -0.365 -0.397 -.030 Regulation ---> (0.167) 0.225 .265 Mkt/Ind structure -2.087 -1.618 -.113 v 4, v T 0.026 0.192 .483 Economic env --—> (0.066) 0.090 .233 Innovation Invst 0.374 1.850 2.208 V4,V2 -0.165 -0.330 .180 Regulation --> (0.070) 0.089 .231 Innovation Invst -2. 128 -3 .217 . 8 32 van? 0.856 0.685 -.218 Mkt/Ind structure --> (0.075) 0.107 .232 Innovation Invst 11.307 6.049 -.995 V5,V4 0.901 0.846 .890 Innovation Invst—--> (0.085) 0. 167 . l 20 Foreign Mkt invst 10.777 5.263 7.319 v6,v4 1561 1.537 -.885 Innovation Invst---> (0.170) 0.235 .497 Global Innovation 9.310 6.882 -1.672 v6,v§ ofi -O.885 .9_47 Foreign Mkt Invst--> (0.168) 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3 .962 1 .790 v 7 , v6 0.896 0.848 -.008 Global Innovation--> (0.086) 0.164 .267 Global Sales 10.489 5.306 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 22.16,12 7.207,]2 13.007,12 p—value 0.046 0.843 .368 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1 .000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefl'rrcient, b = standard error, c =t-va1ue v1= gnp; v2= pricereg, v3= mktsize, v4: r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 160 Table A.2 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Develo in v3,v1 03363 -0.67 -.256 1 Economic env --> 0 168b 0.287 .247 Mkt/Ind structure ' -0.573 -1.008 -1.91 1c ——3_2v ,v 0.726 019‘? .181 Regulation ---> 0.168 0.287 .247 Mkt/Ind structure 1.287 0.664 .714 v4,vI 0.241 0.558 .417— Economic env --> 0.163 0.130 .224 Innovation Invst 1.385 3.680 1.980 v4,v2 -0.511 -0.685 .252 Regulation ---> 0.158 0.131 .221 Innovation Invst -3 .044 -4.545 1 .217 v4,v3 0.147; 0.418 -.372 Mkt/Ind structure --> 0.176 0.135 .234 Innovation Invst 0.825 2.732 -1.735 ‘_"'_5v ,v4 0.901 0.847 .890 Innovation Invst-nu) 0.084 0. 1 66 . 1 20 Foreign Mkt invst 10.79 5.274 7.319 v6,v4 1.561 1.538 -.885 Innovation Invst—--> 0.170 0.234 .497 Global Innovation 9.312 6.886 -1.672 v*6,v§ 07—76 0885 .947— Foreign Mkt Invst--> -0.779 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3.962 1.790 v7 , v6 0.896 0.848 -.008 Global Innovation--> 0.904 0.164 .267 Global Sales 10.498 5.313 -.031 F‘it Indices Chi-square, (if 22. 15, 12 6940,12 12.40, 12 p-value 0.035 0.861 .413 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= gnp; v2= pricereg, v3= mktfocus, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7: gblsales 161 Table A.3 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developin v3,v1 -o,191a -0.079 -.l86 Economic env ---> 0.190!) 0.296 .258 Mkt/Ind structure -10037c -0.226 -.746 __T‘Zv ,v 02—12 0.137 “3713 Regulation ---> 0.190 0.296 .258 Mkt/Ind structure —l.147 0.461 -1.258 v4 , v 1 0.182 0.500 .468 Economic env --> 0.158 0.158 .235 Innovation Invst 1.085 2.759 2.1 18 v4,v2 -0.490 -063? .115 Regulation ---> 0.159 0.159 .244 Innovation Invst -2.905 -3.467 .501 v4,v3 0057 0.209 -.i30 Mkt/Ind structure --> 0.157 0.160 .239 Innovation Invst -0.334 1.143 —.987 V5,V4 0.901 0.847% .890 Innovation Invst-----> 0.084 0. 166 . 1 20 Foreign Mkt invst 10.794 5.283 7.319 v6,v4 1.562 1.539 -.885 Innovation Invst-~--> 0.170 0.234 .497 Global Innovation 9.3 13 6.889 -1 .672 v 6,3 ~0.776 -0.885 .947 Foreign Mkt Invst--> 0.168 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3 .962 1 .790 v 7,V6 0.896 0.849 -.008 Global Innovation--> 0.904 0.163 .267 Global Sales 10.502 5.318 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 2280,12 6641,12 12.485,12 p-value 0.046 0.88 .407 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.995 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= gnp; v2= pricereg, v3= mktgrwth, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 162 Table A.4 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing ‘ v 3 , v 1 -,421a 0.069 .036 Economic env --> . 18 4b 0.284 .262 Mkt/Ind structure -2.408° 0.242 . 135 v3,v2 -.171 -0.300 -.164 Regulation --—> . 184 0.284 .262 Mkt/Ind structure -.978 -1.047 -.621 v4,v1 .114 0.499 .489 Economic env ---> .171 0.157 .182 Innovation Invst .628 2.763 2.863 v4,v7 -.510 -0.671 .2——78 Regulation ---> . 158 0. 164 . 184 Innovation Invst -3.042 -3.549 1.606 V4,v3 -.186 -0.225 .553 Mkt/Ind structure --> .165 0.166 .185 Innovation Invst - l .008 -1.188 3.191 ' v3,v4 .901 0.847 .890 Innovation Invst-«—> .086 0. 166 . 1 20 Foreign Mkt invst 10.598 5.275 7.319 V6,V4 1.562 1.538 -.885 Innovation Invst---> .173 0.234 .497 Global Innovation 9.140 6.887 -1.672 v6,vT -.776 0885 94—7 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .172 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.540 -3 .962 1 .790 V ’,V6 .896 0.848 -.008 Global Innovation-m) .088 0.164 .267 Global Sales 10.310 5.314 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 33.73,l2 8.76,12 13.62 p-value 0.001 0.72 .325 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.999 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= gnp; v2= pricereg, v3= mktconc, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 163 Table A.5 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developin v3,v1 0.431a 0.578 -.029 Economic env ---> 0.174b 0.241 .262 Mkt/Ind structure 2.4830 2.382 -.112 V3,V2 -0.009 0.130 -.175 Regulation ---> 0. 174 0.241 . 262 Mkt/Ind structure -0.051 0.534 -.666 V4,V1 0.140 0.261 .576 Economic env --> 0.074 0.127 .220 Innovation Invst 1.893 2.049 2.536 V 4 , V2 -0.055 -0.058 -.329 Regulation ---> 0.067 0.104 .223 Innovation Invst -0.820 -0.55 8 -1.595 v4,v3 0.868 0.768 -.262 Mkt/Ind structure --> 0.074 0.129 .224 Innovation Invst 1 1.774 5.975 -1.267 V5,V4 0.913 0.877 .893 Innovation Invst ----- > 0.079 0.145 . 1 18 Foreign Mkt invst 1 1.599 6.043 7.416 v6,v4 1.589 1.612 -.896 Innovation Invst-«--> 0.168 0.226 .496 Global Innovation 9.433 7. l3 1 -1 .676 V 6 , V5 -0.7—79 -0.896 .957 Foreign Mkt Invst--> 0.168 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3.962 1.790 v 7 , v6 0.906 0.868 -.008 Global Innovation—--> 0.082 0.150 .267 Global Sales 1 1.089 5.807 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 32.41,12 13.76,12 11.622,12 p—value 0.001 0.315 .476 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.998 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t—value v1= gnp; v2= apptime, v3= mktsize, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 164 Table A.6 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing ‘ v 3, v 1 -0. 530a -0.322 -.342 Economic env --> 0.16313 0.252 .250 Mkt/Ind structure 3394‘: -1.306 -1.363 '—3—'v ,v2 0.247 0.476 -.035 Regulation —--> 0.163 0.252 .250 Mkt/Ind structure 1.583 1.928 -.141 v4,vI 0.572 0.821 .404 Economic env ---> 0.198 0.208 .225 Innovation Invst 2.927 3.938 1.942 v4,v2 -009 -0130 -.294 Regulation ---> 0.173 0.224 .21 1 Innovation Invst —0.523 -0.578 -1.502 v4,v3 0.110 0.359 -.353 Mkt/Ind structure --> 0.195 0.232 .226 Innovation Invst 0.547 1.5 16 -1.696 fiv ,v4 0.913 0.8% .893—— Innovation Invst-«-> 0.079 0.145 .1 18 Foreign Mkt invst 1 1.602 6.043 7.416 v6,v4 1.589 1.612 -.896 Innovation Invst-«--> 0.168 0.226 .496 Global Innovation 9.433 7.131 -1.676 v 6, v5 -0.779 -0.896 .957 ‘ Foreign Mkt Invst--> 0.168 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3 .962 1 .790 V7 , V6 0.906 0.868 -.008 Global Innovation----> 0.082 0.150 .267 Global Sales 1 1.092 5.807 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 17.5,12 1151,12 1129,12 p-value 0.1303 0.485 .503 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.998 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= gnp; v2= apptime, v3= mktfocus, v4= r&dexpd, v5: frginvst, v6= innovat, v7: gblsales 165 Table A.7 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industfialized DeveIoping , v 3 , v 1 -0.0663 -0.197 .033 Economic env --> 0.192!) 0.281 .267 Mkt/Ind structure -0.346C -0.706 .123 ‘ V3, V2 0.058 0.329 -.054 Regulation ---> 0.192 0.281 .267 Mkt/Ind structure 0.300 1.180 -.202 v4,vl 0314 0:31 .53—2 Economic env --> 0.167 0.214 .220 Innovation Invst 3.1 16 3.403 2.61 1 V4,V2 -0.062 -0.002 -.297 Regulation ---> 0.167 0.222 .220 Innovation Invst -0.378 -0.009 -1.455 v4,v§ 0.001 0.171 -.253 Mkt/Ind structure --> 0.167 0.225 .220 Innovation Invst 0.008 0.577 -1 .241 _—5v ,v4 0.913 0.877 89—3 Innovation Invst-—--> 0.079 0.145 .1 18 Foreign Mkt invst 1 1.603 6.043 7.416 v€,v4 1.589 1.613 -.896 Innovation Invst—--—> 0.168 0.226 .496 Global Innovation 9.433 7. 13 1 -1 .676 v6,v§ 0.779 -0.896 .957 Foreign Mkt Invst--> 0.168 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3.962 1.790 v7 , v6 0.906 0.868 -.008 Global Innovation----> 0.082 0.150 .267 Global Sales 1 1.092 5.807 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 48.79,12 7.726,12 10.357,12 p-value 0.001 0.8061 .584 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.996 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= gnp; v2= apptime, v3= mktgrwth, v4: r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 166 Table A.8 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing v 3, v 1 -o,352a 0.225 .086 Economic env ~-> 0 180b 0.293 .263 Mkt/Ind structure ' 0.768 .327 -2.05c ‘ v3,v2 0.166 0.033 .113 Regulation ---> 0.180 0.293 .263 Mkt/Ind structure 0.938 0.1 13 .429 v 4 , v 1 0.474 0.722 .478 Economic env --> 0.178 0.217 .172 Innovation Invst 2.699 3.31 1 3.003 V 4 , V2 -0.044 0.044 -.342 Regulation ---> 0.168 0.212 .172 Innovation Invst -0.264 0.205 -2.143 v4,v3 -0.111 -0.071 .5718 Mkt/Ind structure --> 0.177 0.217 .174 Innovation Invst -0.621 -0.326 3.420 v3,v4 0.913 0.877 .893 Innovation Invst—--> 0.079 0.145 . 1 18 Foreign Mkt invst 1 1.604 6.043 7.416 v6,v4 1.58 1.613 -.896 Innovation Invst—«-> 0.168 0.226 .496 Global Innovation 9.433 7.131 -1.676 v 6, v5 -0.779 -0.896 .957 Foreign Mkt Invst--> 0.168 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3.962 1.790 V 7, V6 0.906 0.868 -.008 Global Innovation—-> 0.082 0.150 .267 Global Sales 1 1.093 5.807 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 41.26,12 10.631,12 13.007,12 p-value 0.001 0.560 .368 BBFI 1.000 1.000 .999 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= gnp; v2= apptime, v3= mktconc, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 167 Table A.9 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall IndustrIaIized Developing v3,v1 0372a 0.984 .618 Economic env --> 0. 15313 0.054 .221 Mkt/Ind structure 2.7269 18.48 3.263 1 v3 , v2 -0.60 0.034 -.340 Regulation ---> 0. 153 0.054 . 221 Mkt/Ind structure -4.406 0.630 -1.792 v4,v1 0.048 0.613 -.03_2 Economic env --> 0.073 0.479 .337 Innovation Invst 0.744 1.095 -.096 vai -0.184 0859 -.105 Regulation ---> 0.084 0.086 .282 Innovation Invst -2.481 -3.564 -.371 v4,v3 0.817 0.267 -.300 Mkt/Ind structure --> 0.081 0.469 .308 Innovation Invst 10.207 0.476 -.835 V5 , V4 0.929 0.842 .878 ‘ Innovation Invst----> 0.070 0. 169 . 1 28 Foreign Mkt invst 13.031 5.186 6.867 V6,V4 1.62 1.528 -.830 Innovation Invst---> 0.165 0.236 .504 Global Innovation 9.600 6.853 —1.649 v6,v? -0785 -0.884 .901 Foreign Mkt Invst--> 0.168 0.226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3.962 1.790 1 V ’,V6 0.920 0.846 -.008 Global Innovation----> 0.074 0.165 .267 Global Sales 12.157 5.258 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, (1f 2729,12 9499,12 11.604,12 p-value 0.007 0.659 .477 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= pop; v2= pricereg, v3= mktsize, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 168 Table A.10 Global Innovation Model ‘ Paths Overall Industrialized DeveIoping v3,vl 0155:: 0.503 . 17 Economic env --> 0.171b 0.250 .244 Mkt/Ind structure 0.8809 2.459 1.265 ——'3_2v ,v 0.3—76 0.534 .139 Regulation ---> 0. 171 0.250 .244 Mkt/Ind structure 2.137 2.609 .554 v4,v1 0.346 0.876 -.07T—* Economic env --> 0.144 0.106 .247 Innovation Invst 2.736 7.013 -.295 V4,V2 -0.689 -.350 .060 Regulation ---> 0.153 .109 .237 Innovation Invst -5.1 12 -2.746 .25 1 v4, v 3 0.039 -.000 -.454 Mkt/Ind structure --> 0.159 .103 .257 Innovation Invst 0.285 -.002 -1.817 —v5,v4 0.929 .842 .87—8 Innovation Invst-~-> 0.070 . 170 . 1 28 Foreign Mkt invst 13.03 5.168 6.867 v6,v4 1.62 1.526 -.830 Innovation Invst—-> 0.165 .236 .504 Global Innovation 9.60 6.846 -1.649 v6,v5 -0.785 -.883 .901 Foreign Mkt Invst--> 0.168 .226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3.962 1.790 V 7, V6 0.920 .845 -.008 Global Innovation—--> 0.074 0.166 .267 Global Sales 12.159 5.247 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 983,12 823,12 13.09,12 p-value 0.070 0.766 .362 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= pop; v2= pricereg, v3= mktfocus, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7: gblsales Table A.ll Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing v 3 , v 1 0,093a .089 .25 I Economic env --> 0 1911) .296 .256 Mkt/Ind structure ° .306 1.036 .489c _flv ,v -.120 .271 -347— Regulation ---> .191 .296 .256 Mkt/Ind structure -.630 .793 -1.434 v4,v1 .358 .863 -.146 Economic env --> . 141 .079 .260 Innovation Invst 2.882 9.365 -.559 v4,v2 -.686 -.383 -.104 Regulation .....> . 142 .080 .269 Innovation Invst -5.507 -4.054 -.388 VLW -.088 .138 -.290 Mkt/Ind structure -—> .141 .080 .262 Innovation Invst -.700 1.454 -1.043 ‘fiv ,v4 .929 .842 .878 Innovation Invst----> .070 . 170 . 1 28 Foreign Mkt invst 13.040 5.172 6.867 v6,v4 1.629 1.527 -.830 Innovation Invst----> 0.165 .236 .504 Global Innovation 9.601 6.848 - l .649 V6,V5 -. 85 -.883 .901 Foreign Mkt Invst--> 0.168 .226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3.962 1.790 v7,v6 .920 .845 -.008 Global Innovation----> .074 .166 .267 Global Sales 12.163 5.249 -.031 F'it Indices Chi-square, df 2081,12 7932,12 1229,12 p—value 0.053 .790 .422 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1 .000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= pop; v2= pricereg, v3= mktgrwth, v4: r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 170 Table A.12 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Indust_rialized Developing ‘ v 3,v 1 00298 -.304 .092 Economic env -—-> 0 1941) .273 .262 Mkt/Ind structure ' -1.227 .356 .149c v3,v2 .117 -.484 -.243 Regulation —--> .194 .273 .262 Mkt/Ind structure .601 - l .957 -.944 v4,v1 .356 .876 ‘ -.280 Economic env --> . 139 .091 .205 Innovation Invst 2.907 8.208 -1.366 v4,v2 -.655 -.349 .148 Regulation ---> . 140 .099 .210 Innovation Invst -5.307 -3.001 .703 v4,v3 -.174 .001 .628 Mkt/Ind structure -—> .141 .094 .208 Innovation Invst -1.409 .01 1 2.970 v3,v4 .929 .842 .878 ‘ Innovation Invst-—-> .07 1 . 170 . 128 Foreign Mkt invst 12.799 5.172 6.867 v6,v4 1.629 1.527 -.830 Innovation Invst---> . 168 .236 .504 Global Innovation 9.420 6.849 -1.649 V6,V5 T785 -.884 .901 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .172 .226 .504 Global Innovation -4.540 -3.962 1.790 V1,, V6 .920 .846 -.008 Global Innovation--> .076 . 165 .267 Global Sales 1 1.936 5.252 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 2544,12 8476,12 13.59, 12 p-value 0.012 .746 .327 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= pop; v2= pricereg, v3= mktconc, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6: innovat, v7: gblsales Table A.l3 Global Innovation Model Paths Overafi Industrialized Developing v3,v1 0.1272! .983 .4 7 Economic env --> 0 189b .055 .235 Mkt/Ind structure ' 17.934 1.928 .676c ‘ V3,V2 .158 .024 -.070 Regulation ---> . 189 .055 .235 Mkt/Ind structure .839 .434 -.297 v4,v1 -.074 .888 -.142"'_" Economic env --> .070 .609 .285 Innovation Invst - 1.05 1 .469 -.501 v4,vT -031 -.040 -.118 Regulation ---> .071 .1 12 .254 Innovation Invst -.446 -.365 -.468 V4,V3 .943 .043 -.232 Mkt/Ind structure --> .071 .612 .288 Innovation Invst 13.24 .07 l -.8 16 ‘ v3,v4 .911 .879 .880 Innovation Invst--> .079 . 144 . 1 27 Foreign Mkt invst 1 1.49 6.106 6.920 v6,v4 1.58 1.618 -.837 Innovation Invst---> . 168 .226 .503 Global Innovation 9 .41 7. 148 -1 .652 v6,v5 -.7_79 -.897 .907 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .168 .226 .504 Global Innovation —4.62 -3.962 1.790 v7,v6 .904 .870 -.008 Global Innovation-«9 .082 .149 .267 Global Sales 1 1.009 5.849 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 27.9,12 9.691,12 9972,12 p-value 0.005 .643 . 18 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1 .000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= pop; v2= apptime, v3= mktsize, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales Table A.14 Global Innovation Model , Paths Overall Industrialized Developin v3,v1 0,343a .138 .369 Economic env --> 0.18013 .267 .245 Mkt/Ind structure 1951‘: .511 1.496 v3 , v2 .144 .423 «.099 Regulation ---> . 180 .267 .245 Mkt/Ind structure .807 1.569 -.399 v4,v1 .136 .949 -.075 Economic env --> . 199 . 106 .249 Innovation Invst .686 9.021 - . 301 V4,fi .153 .017 -.l48 Regulation ---> .189 .116 .233 Innovation Invst .809 . 148 -.639 v4,v3 -.229 -.133 -.468 Mkt/Ind structure --> .199 .118 .253 Innovation Invst -1.14 -1. 149 -1.880 , v3,v4 .911 .879 .880 Innovation Invst--> .079 . 144 . 127 Foreign Mkt invst 1 1.493 6.106 6.920 v6,v4 1.58 1.618 -.837 Innovation Invst----> .168 .226 .5 03 Global Innovation 9.418 7.148 -1.652 v6,v5 -.779 -.897 90—7 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .168 .226 .504 Global Innovation -4.627 -3.962 1.790 V17 , V6 .904 .820 —.008 Global Innovation—~> .082 .149 .267 Global Sales 1 1.012 5.849 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 15.92,12 7.790,12 1 196,12 p-value 0.19 .780 .448 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= pop; v2= apptime, v3= mktfocus, v4= r&dexpd, v5: frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 173 Table A.15 Global Innovation Model , Paths Overall Industrialized Developing v3,vI 0.0463 -.115 .024 ‘ Economic env --> 0 192b .285 .267 Mkt/Ind structure ' -.406 .091 .237c v3,v2 .045 .325 -.033 Regulation —--> . 192 .285 .267 Mkt/Ind structure .234 1.148 -.123 v4,v1 .058 .941 —.241 Economic env ---> . 19 1 . 109 .250 Innovation Invst .305 8.723 -.971 v4,vf .121 -.069 -.110 Regulation —---> . 191 . 1 14 .250 Innovation Invst .634 -.606 -.443 v4,v3 40372 .090 -.2—52 Mkt/Ind structure --> .191 .114 .250 Innovation Invst -. 168 .786 -1.015 V5,V4 .911 .879 .880 Innovation Invst----> .079 . 144 . 1 27 Foreign Mkt invst 11.49 6.106 6.920 V6,V4 1.58 1.618 -.837 Innovation Invst----> .168 .226 .5 03 Global Innovation 9.41 7 . 148 -1 .652 _v6,v5 -.7_79 -.897 .907— Foreign Mkt Invst--> .168 .226 .504 Global Innovation -4.62 -3 .962 1 .790 V 7,V6 .904 .870 -.008 Global Innovation---> .082 .149 .267 Global Sales 1 1.01 5.849 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 15.66, 12 8.064,12 10.876,12 p-value 0.20 .780 .539 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1 .000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1: pop; v2= apptime, v3= mktgrwth, v4= r&dexpd, v5: frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 174 Table A.16 Global Innovation Model Paths Overfil jndustriglizefi Develo in v3,vf 0,095a -.017 -.021 Economic env --> 0 1911) .301 .264 Mkt/Ind structure ° -.057 -.078 .498c v 3, v 2 .066 .065 .148 Regulation ---> .191 .301 .264 Mkt/Ind structure .347 .215 .560 v4,v1 .083 .922 -.235 1 Economic env --> .184 .106 .200 Innovation Invst .450 8 .838 -1 . 179 V4,V2 .138 -.046 -.193 Regulation -----> .184 .106 .203 Innovation Invst .750 -.437 -.961 V4,V3 -.2_75 .104 .618 Mkt/Ind structure ...> . 185 . 106 .203 Innovation Invst -1.49 .984 3.072 —_—5v ,v4 .911 .879 .880 Innovation Invst----> .079 . 144 . 127 Foreign Mkt invst 1 1.49 6.106 6.920 V6,V4 1.58 1.618 -.837 ‘ Innovation Invst----> . 168 .226 .503 Global Innovation 9 .4 1 7 . 148 - 1 .652 v6,v5 -.7‘79 -897 .907—__— Foreign Mkt Invst--> .168 .226 .504 Global Innovation -4.62 -3.962 1.790 V ’,V6 .904 .870 -.008 Global Innovation----> .082 . 149 .267 Global Sales 1 1.01 5.849 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 1643,12 8804,12 13.483.12 p—value 0.17 .719 .334 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1= pop; v2= apptime, v3= mktconc, v4= r&dexpd, v5= frginvst, v6= innovat, v7= gblsales 175 Table A.l7 Global Innovation Model . Paths Overall Industpialized Developin v3,v1 0.190%: .423 -.129 Economic env --> 0.16713 .225 .265 Mkt/Ind structure 1.08 4c 1.725 -.486 v3,v2 -.362 -.397 -.030 Regulation ---> .167 .225 .265 Mkt/Ind structure -2.078 -1.618 -.113 v4,v1 .026 .192 .48_3 ‘ Economic env --> .066 .090 .233 Innovation Invst .374 1.850 2.208 v4,v2 -.165 -.330 .180 Regulation ----> .070 .089 .231 Innovation Invst —2.2 1 8 -3.217 .832 V4,V3 .856 .685 —.218 Mkt/Ind structure --> .075 .107 .232 Innovation Invst l 1.30 6.049 -.995 v5,v4 .135 -.241 .580 Innovation Invst-«--> .203 .334 .209 Foreign Mkt invst .710 -.825 2.665 V6,V4 .876 .691 -.220 Innovation Invst----> .098 . 155 .298 Global Innovation 9. 1 0 1 4.677 - .694 v6,v§ -.105 -.402 .308 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation - l .089 -2.720 .972 ‘ v7,v6 .896 .848 -.008 Global Innovation----> .086 . 164 .267 Global Sales 10.489 5.306 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 24.99,12 9.8,12 13.889,12 p-VEtlue 0.014 .633 .307 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1 .000 BBNFI 1.000 1 .000 1 .000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales 176 Table A.18 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Tndustfiafized Develo in v3,v1 -.3363 -.164 -.256 ‘ Economic env --> 0 1689 .287 .247 Mkt/Ind structure ' -.562 -1.008 -1.911° ‘ V3,V2 .226 .191 .181 Regulation ——--> .168 .287 .247 Mkt/Ind structure 1.287 .655 .714 v4,vl .241 .32 .417 Economic env --> .163 .130 .224 Innovation Invst 1.385 3.695 1.980 v4,v2 -.511 -.684 .252 Regulation ---> . 158 . 13 1 .221 Innovation Invst -3.044 -4.554 1.217 v4,v3 .147 .416 -.372 ‘ Mkt/Ind structure --> .176 .135 .234 Innovation Invst .825 2.732 - l .735 ‘ v5,v4 .136 -.2712 .580 Innovation Invst--> .203 .332 .209 Foreign Mkt invst .71 1 -.829 2.665 v6,v4 87-7 .693 -.220 Innovation Invst----> .098 .155 .298 Global Innovation 9.1 11 4.699 -.694 v6,v5 -.105 -.401 .308 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v7,v6 .896 .849 -.008 Global Innovation—-> .086 .163 .267 Global Sales 10.498 5.323 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 22.35,12 7.819,]2 11.934,12 p—value 0.033 .799 .450 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=gnp; v2qyricereg; v3antfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales 177 Table A.19 Global Innovation Model Paths Overail Industrialized Developing ‘ v3,v1 -0.191a -.079 -.186 Economic env --> 0.190!) .296 .258 Mkt/Ind structure -1.037c -.266 -.746 "fifl ,v -.21_2 .137 -.313 Regulation ---> . 190 .296 .258 Mkt/Ind structure -1.147 .461 -1.258 v4,vl .182 .500 .468 Economic env --> .158 .158 .235 Innovation Invst 1.085 2.759 2.1 18 v4,vf -.490 —.63T .115 Regulation ---> . 159 . 159 .244 Innovation Invst ~2.905 —3.467 .501 v4,v3 -.057 .209 T230 Mkt/Ind structure --> .157 .160 .239 Innovation Invst -.334 1.143 -.987 v3,v4 .136 -.2_2 .580 Innovation Invst---> .203 .333 .209 Foreign Mkt invst .71 1 -.828 2.665 v6,v4 87—7 .692 -.2T—2 ‘ Innovation Invst----> .098 . 155 .298 Global Innovation 9.1 15 4.693 -.694 v6,v5 -.105 -.401 .308 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v7,v6 .896 .849 -.008 Global Innovation-«9 .086 .163 .267 Global Sales 10.502 5.318 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 20.87,]2 7.267, 12 13.028,12 p—value 0.05 .839 .366 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.980 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 0.997 CFI 1.000 1.000 0.998 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat;v7=gblsales Table A.20 Global Innovation Model Path OveralI Industrialized Develofin v3,v1 -,421a .069 .036 Economic env --> 0. 1819 .284 .262 Mkt/Ind structure -2. 4 54c .242 .135 ___an ,v -.171 -300 -.164 Regulation ---> . 18 1 .284 .262 Mkt/Ind structure —.996 -1.047 -.621 V4,V1 .114 .499 .489 Economic env --> .168 .157 .182 Innovation Invst .640 2.763 2.863 v4,v2 45710 -.671 .278 Regulation --—-> . 155 . 164 . 184 Innovation Invst -3. 100 -3.549 1.606 V4,V3 -.186 -.225 .553 Mkt/Ind structure --> .162 .166 .185 Innovation Invst -1.027 -1. 188 3 . 191 V5,V4 :136 -.242 .580 Innovation Invst---> .202 .333 .209 Foreign Mkt invst .71 1 -.827 2.665 v6,v4 .877 .692 -.220 Innovation Invst---> .098 .155 .298 Global Innovation 9. 12 4.687 -.694 v6,v§ -.105 -.401 .308 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v7,v6 .896 .848 -.008 Global Innovation—-> .086 . 164 .267 Global Sales 10.506 5.314 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 2083,12 11.399,12 14.227, 12 p-value 0.05 .49 .286 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.991 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 0.998 CFI 1.000 1.000 0.999 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=gnp; v2=pricereg; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales Table A.2] Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrjplized Developing , v 3,v 1 0,432a .578 -.029 Economic env —-> 0. 174b .241 .262 Mkt/Ind structure 2.486c 2.382 -.112 v3,v2 -.009 .130 -.175 Regulation ---> . 1 74 .24 1 .262 Mkt/Ind structure -.051 .534 -.666 v4,vl .140 .261 .576 1 Economic env -~> .074 .127 .220 Innovation Invst 1.901 2.048 2.536 V4,V2 -.053 -.058 -.329 Regulation ----> .067 .104 .223 Innovation Invst -.799 -.557 -1.595 v4,v3 .8627 .768 -.262 Mkt/Ind structure --> .074 .129 .224 Innovation Invst 1 1.773 5.975 -1.267 ‘ v3,v4 .146 -.275 .585 Innovation Invst—«-> . 1 88 .291 . 206 Foreign Mkt invst .764 -.947 2.700 v6,v4 .892 .7—25 -.223 Innovation Invst—m) .09 1 . 136 . 295 Global Innovation 9.785 5.321 -.700 v6,vr -.099 -.371 .310 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v7,v6 .906 .868 -.008 Global Innovation-«0 .082 .150 .267 Global Sales 1 1.094 5.807 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 22. 10,12 10.005,12 10.647 , 1 2 p-value 0.036 .615 .559 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.990 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales Table A.22 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industfialized Developing v3,vl -.529a -.322 -.342 Economic env —--> 1639 .252 .250 Mkt/Ind structure ' - 1 .306 -1 .363 -3.38c v3 , vT .277 .476 -.035 Regulation ---> . 163 .252 .250 Mkt/Ind structure 1.58 1.928 -.141 v4,vl .371 .821 .404 Economic env --> .195 .208 .225 Innovation Invst 2.932 3.938 1.942 v4,v2 -.09 -.130 -.294 Regulation ---> . 173 .224 .21 1 Innovation Invst -.526 -.578 -1.502 V4,“ .110 .59 -.353 Mkt/Ind structure --> .195 .232 .226 Innovation Invst .547 1 .5 16 -1 .696 V5,V4 .146 -.275 .585 Innovation Invst---> . 1 88 . 291 . 206 Foreign Mkt invst .765 -.947 2.700 v6,v4 .892 .725 -.223 Innovation Invst---> .09 1 . 1 36 .295 Global Innovation 9.786 5.321 -.700 v6,v5 -.099 -.371 .310 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation - l .089 -2.720 .972 V 7,V6 .906 .868 -.008 Global Innovation--> .082 . 150 .267 Global Sales 1 1.094 5.807 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 1911,12 9440,12 11.309,12 p—value 0.08 .664 .502 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.983 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, e = t-value v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales 181 Table A.23 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Develo in v3,vl -.0653 -.197 .033 Economic env --> .1921) .281 .267 Mkt/Ind structure _339‘: -.706 .123 v3,v2 .058 .329 -.054 Regulation ---> . 192 .281 .267 Mkt/Ind structure .301 1.180 -.202 v4,v1 .515 .721 .532 Economic env ---> . 167 .214 .220 Innovation Invst 3.1 19 3.403 2.611 NEW -.063 -.002 -297"— Regulation ---> .167 .222 .220 Innovation Invst -.3 82 -.009 -1.455 v4,v3 .001 .131 -.2—53 " Mkt/Ind structure --> .167 .225 .220 Innovation Invst .008 .577 - 1 .241 ‘ v5,v4 .146 -275 .585 Innovation Invst--> . 188 . 29 1 . 206 Foreign Mkt invst .765 -.947 2.700 v6,v4 .892 .725 -.223 Innovation Invst---> .09 1 . 1 36 . 295 Global Innovation 9.786 5.321 -.700 v6,v5 -.099 -371 .310 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation - l .089 -2.720 .972 ‘ V17,V6 .906 .868 -.008 Global Innovation—-> .082 . 150 .267 Global Sales 1 1.094 5.808 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 1682,12 9373,12 9937,12 p-value 0.156 .67 .62 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.990 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, e = t-value v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales 182 Table A.24 Global Innovation Model Paths OveraTl Industrialized Developing v ,vl -,361a .225 .086 Economic env --> .180b .293 .263 Mkt/Ind structure _2.041c .768 .327 v3,v2 .166 .033 .113 Regulation ---> . 180 .293 .263 Mkt/Ind structure .938 .1 13 .429 v4,v1 4'3 .722 .4—78 ‘ Economic env ---> .178 .217 .172 Innovation Invst 2.703 3.31 1 3.003 vIvT -.045 .044 -.342 Regulation ---> . 168 . 2 12 . 172 Innovation Invst -.273 .205 -2.143 v4,v3 -.110 -.071 .548 Mkt/Ind structure --> .177 .217 .174 Innovation Invst -.621 -.326 3.420 v3,v4 .146 -.2 5 .585 Innovation Invst---> . l 88 . 29 1 . 206 Foreign Mkt invst .765 -.947 2.700 v6,v4 .892 .225 -.223 Innovation Invst----> .09 1 . 136 .295 Global Innovation 9.786 5.321 -.700 v6,vf -.099 -.371 .310 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 V 7, V6 .906 .868 -.008 Global Innovation--—> .08 1 . 150 .267 Global Sales 1 1.095 5.807 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square,df 41.93,12 11.771,12 13.316,12 p-value 0.001 .464 .346 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=gnp; v2=apptime; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales Table A.25 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing . v3,vr 0,371a .984 .618 Economic env --> 0 1531) .054 .221 Mkt/Ind structure ' 18.48 3.263 2.726 v3,v2 -.601 .034 -.340 Regulation ---> . 153 .054 .221 Mkt/Ind structure -4.412 .630 -1.792 v4,v1 .046 .612 -.032 Economic env --> .073 .479 .337 Innovation Invst .714 1.095 -.096 v4,vf -.186 -.359 -.105 Regulation ---> .084 .086 .282 Innovation Invst -2.507 -3.564 -.371 V4,V3 .816 .267 -.300 Mkt/Ind structure --> .081 .469 .308 Innovation Invst 10.20 .476 -.835 v5,v4 .163 338 .256 Innovation Invst---> . 168 .339 .222 Foreign Mkt invst .859 -.813 2.500 v6,v4 .914 .6fi -.——207 Innovation Invst----> .081 .157 .3 1 1 Global Innovation 10.966 4.61 3 -.665 v6,v5 -.091 -.405 .302— Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 _—‘7v ,v6 mo .846 -.008 Global Innovation---> .074 .165 .267 Global Sales 12.165 5.258 -.031 ‘ Fitjndices Chi-square, df 21.24,12 11.216,12 12.237,12 p—value 0.046 .5 1 .426 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.992 BBNFI 1.000 1 .000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c =t-va1ue v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales Table A.26 Global Innovation Model ‘ Paths Overall Industrialized Developing , v3,v1 0.155a .5_03 .317 Economic env --> 0 1711) .250 .244 Mkt/Ind structure ' 2.459 1.265 .880c V3,V2 .376 .534 .1329 Regulation --> . 17 1 .250 .244 Mkt/Ind structure 2.137 2.609 .554 v4,vl .346 .876 -.073 Economic env --> .144 .106 .247 Innovation Invst 2.736 7.01 3 -.295 v4 , VT -.689 -.350 .060 Regulation ~--> . 1 53 . 109 .237 Innovation Invst -5.1 12 -2.746 .251 v4 , v3 .039 -.000 -.454 Mkt/Ind structure ---> .159 .103 .257 Innovation Invst .285 -.002 -1 .8 l 7 v 5 , v4 . 163 -.237 .556 1 Innovation Invst---> . 168 .340 .222 Foreign Mkt invst .859 -.810 2.500 VCV4 .914 .687 -.207 Innovation Invst---> .081 . 158 .3 1 1 Global Innovation 10.961 4.597 - .665 v6,v5 -.091 -.406 .302— Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 :31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v7,v6 .920 .845 -.008 Global Innovation—«> .074 . 166 .267 Global Sales 12.161 5.247 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 25.61,12 8.982,12 13.709,12 p-value 0.012 .704 .319 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.990 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 0.998 CFI 1.000 1.000 0.999 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, e = t-value v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales 185 Table A.27 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Develo in v 3, v 1 0,095a .089 .250 Economic env --> 0 1911) .296 .256 Mkt/Ind structure ° .306 1.036 _501c _ij ,v -.119 .231 -347— Regulation ---> . 191 .296 .256 Mkt/Ind structure -.625 .793 - l .434 V4,V1 .360 .863 -.146 Economic env --> . 141 .079 .260 Innovation Invst 2.893 9.365 -.559 V4,?2 -.686 -.383 -.104 Regulation ---> .142 .080 .269 Innovation Invst -5.502 -4.054 -.388 V4,V3 -.088 .138 -.290 Mkt/Ind structure --> .141 .080 .262 Innovation Invst -.700 1.454 -1.043 v5,v4 .163 -.23’7 .556 Innovation Invst---> .168 .340 .222 Foreign Mkt invst .859 -.811 2.500 v6,v4 .914 .687 -.207 Innovation Invst--> .081 . 158 .3 1 1 Global Innovation 10.963 4.601 -.665 V6,V5 -.091 -.406 .302 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v 7 ,v6 .920 .845 -.008 Global Innovation--> .074 .166 .267 Global Sales 12. 163 5.249 -.03 1 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 21.06,12 8.792,12 1333,12 p—valuc 0.049 .720 .345 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales Table A.28 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing v3 , v 1 0,029a -.304 .092 Economic env ----> 0 191b .273 .262 Mkt/Ind structure ' -1.227 .356 . 152° ——3_2v ,v .117 -.484 -.243 Regulation --«> . 191 . 273 .262 Mkt/Ind structure .612 -1.957 -.944 v4,v1 .356 .87? -.280 Economic env --> . 137 .091 .205 Innovation Invst 2.962 8.208 -1.366 v4,v2 -.655 -.349 .148 Regulation ---> . 138 .099 .2 10 Innovation Invst -5.408 -3.001 .703 v4,v3 -.174 .001 .628 Mkt/Ind structure ...> .138 .094 .208 Innovation Invst - 1.436 .01 1 2.970 ‘ v5,v4 .163 -.238 .556 Innovation Invst---> .168 .340 .222 Foreign Mkt invst .859 -.811 2.500 v6,v4 .914 .682 -.207 ‘ Innovation Invst---> .081 . 158 .3 1 1 Global Innovation 10.967 4.604 -.665 V6,Vr -.091 -.406 .302 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 V ’,V6 .920 .846 -.008 Global Innovation----> .074 . 165 .267 Global Sales 12.167 5 .252 -.031 ‘ Fit Indices Chi-square, df 20.95, 12 10.551,12 14.020,12 p-value 0.05 .567 .299 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.994 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 0.998 CFI 1.000 1.000 0.999 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, e = t-value v1=pop; v2=pricereg; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales 187 Table A.29 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing v3,vl 0.127a .983 .457 Economic env --> 0 189° .055 .235 Mkt/Ind structure ° 17.935 1.929 .676° v3,v2 .158 .024 -.070 Regulation ---> . 189 .055 .235 Mkt/Ind structure .839 .434 -.297 v4,vl -.063 .888 -.141 Economic env --> .071 .609 .285 Innovation Invst -.896 1.468 -.500 v4,v2 -.029 -.041 -.118 Regulation ---> .071 . 1 12 .254 Innovation Invst -.411 -.366 -.467 v4,v3 .942 .043 -.232 Mkt/Ind structure --> .071 .612 .288 Innovation Invst 13.157 .071 -.816 ‘__5v ,v4 .144 5277 .559 Innovation Invst---> . 190 .288 . 22 1 Foreign Mkt invst .757 -.957 2.519 V6,V4 .890 .728 -.208 Innovation Invst----> .092 .135 .3 10 Global Innovation 9.693 5.372 -.668 v6,v5 -.100 -.368 .303 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v7,v6 .904 .870 -.008 Global Innovation---> .082 .149 .267 Global Sales 1 1.012 5.849 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 28.09.12 10.842,12 1 120,12 p—value 0.005 .542 .51 1 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.991 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3antsize; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales Table A.30 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing ‘ v3,v1 0,343a .138 .370 Economic env ---> 0. 1801’ .267 .245 Mkt/Ind structure 1_951c .512 1.497 v3,v2 .144 .423 -.099 Regulation ----> . 180 .267 .245 Mkt/Ind structure .806 1.568 -.399 V4,Vl .136 .949 -.074 Economic env ---> . 199 . 106 .249 Innovation Invst .686 9.023 -.300 v4,v2 .153 .012 -.148 Regulation -----> . 189 . 1 16 .233 Innovation Invst .809 .146 -.638 V4,V3— -.229 -.133 -.468 Mkt/Ind structure ---> .199 .118 .253 Innovation Invst -1. 140 -1.149 -1.880 v5,v4 .144 -.27'_7 .559 Innovation Invst ----- > . 190 .288 .22 1 Foreign Mkt invst .757 -.957 2.519 V6,V4 .890 .728 -.208 Innovation Invst---> .092 . 135 .3 10 Global Innovation 9.69 5.374 —.668 va5 -.100 -.368 .303 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v7,v6 .904 8W -.008 Global Innovation----> .082 .149 .267 Global Sales 11.012 5.850 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 3582,12 8.947,12 12.63,12 p—value 0.001 .707 .396 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.991 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 0.999 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktfocus; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales Table A.31 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industrialized Developing . v3,v1 0.0463 -.115 .024 Economic env ---> 0 1921) .285 .267 Mkt/Ind structure ' -.406 .091 .238° v3,v2 .045 .325 —.033 Regulation ---> .192 .285 .267 Mkt/Ind structure .234 1.148 -.122 v4,vl .058 .941 -.241 Economic env ---> . 19 1 . 109 .250 Innovation Invst .305 8.724 -.971 v4,vf .121 -.069 -.110 Regulation ---> .191 .1 14 .250 Innovation Invst .634 -.606 -.443 v4,v3 -.032 .090 -.252 Mkt/Ind structure --> .191 .114 .250 Innovation Invst -.168 .786 -1.015 v5,v4 .144 -. 77 .559 Innovation Invst-«~> . 190 . 288 . 22 1 Foreign Mkt invst .757 -.957 2.519 V6,V4 .890 .728 -.208 Innovation Invst-«-> .092 . 135 .3 10 Global Innovation 9.693 5.374 -.668 v6,v5 -.100 -.368 .303 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 v7,v6 .904 .870 -.008 Global Innovation-«9 .082 . 149 .267 Global Sales 11.012 5.850 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 1752,12 9960,12 10.413,12 p-value 0.131 0.619 .579 BBFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktgrwth; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales Table A.32 Global Innovation Model Paths Overall Industriglized Developing . v3,v1 0.095a -.017 -.021 Economic env ---> 0.191b .301 .264 Mkt/Ind structure . 498° -.057 -.078 1 v3,v2 .066 .064 .148 Regulation ---> . 191 . 301 .264 Mkt/Ind structure .347 .214 .561 V4,V1 .083 .932 -.235 Economic env -«> . 184 . 106 .200 Innovation Invst .450 8.839 -1 . 180 v4,v22 .138 -.046 —.193 Regulation ---> . 1 84 . 106 .203 Innovation Invst .750 -.437 -.960 V4,V3 -.275 .103 .618 Mkt/Ind structure ---> . 185 . 106 .203 Innovation Invst - 1 .491 .984 3 .072 v5,v4 .144 -.277 .559 Innovation Invst----> . 190 .288 .22 1 Foreign Mkt invst .757 -.957 2.519 V6,V4 .890 .728 -.208 Innovation Invst----> .092 . 135 .3 10 Global Innovation 9.693 5.373 -.668 V6,R -.100 -.368 .303 Foreign Mkt Invst--> .092 .136 .31 1 Global Innovation -1.089 -2.720 .972 _'—'7v ,v6 .904 .870 -.008 Global Innovation----> .082 .149 .267 Global Sales 1 1.012 5.849 -.031 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 16.12,12 10.455,12 12.44,12 p-value 0.18 .576 .410 BBFI 1.000 1.000 0.997 BBNFI 1.000 1.000 1.000 CFI 1.000 1.000 1 .000 a = standardized coefficient, b = standard error, c = t-value v1=pop; v2=apptime; v3=mktconc; v4=r&dexpd; v5=frgcomm; v6=innovat; v7=gblsales APPENDIX B 191 APPENDIX B Table B.l Global Diffusion Model Paths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value v3,vl Economic env ----- m>MktIIndustry structure -.167, .287, -.572 v3,v2 Regulation -------- >Mkt/Industry structure .192, .287, .658 v4,v1 Economic Env ----- >Market Potential .503, .187, 2.472 v4,v2 Regulation-------->Market Potential -.493, .188, -2.410 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure- ------ >Market Potential .484, .194, 2.336 v5,v4 Market Potential ------- >Incoming foreign invst .582, .259, 2.374 v6,v4 Market Potential-~---->Global Diffusion -.1 15, .136, -1.003 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst-------—>Global Diffusion .035, .129, .306 v6,v7 Global Innovation-«~«->Global Diffusion .946, .102, 10.179 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 8.393.12 p—value .753 BBFI .990 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 v1= gnp, v2= pricereg, v3= indfocus, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 192 Table B.2 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value v3,vl Economic env-«~—->Mkt/Industry structure -.082, .296, -.275 v3,v2 Regulation---—->Mktl1ndustry structure .138, .296, .464 v4,vl Economic Env—-—-->Market Potential .426, .226, 1.734 v4,v2 Regulation >Market Potential -.406, .227, -1.643 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure >Market Potential .046, .229, .186 v5,v4 Market Potentia1-—--->Incoming foreign invst .582, .259, 2.374 v6,v4 Market Potential—~-—->Global Diffusion -.1 12, .136, -.976 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst-m—->Global Diffusion .035, .129, .304 v6,v7 Global Innovation--o--->Global Diffusion .946, .102, 10.143 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 8.587,12 p—value .737 BBFI .999 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 v1= gnp, v2= pricereg, v3= indgrwth, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 193 Table B.3 Global Diffusion Model Paths . Coefficients, Standard error, t-value v3,vl Economic env---—-->Mkt/Industry structure -,O67, .284, .234 v3,v2 Regulation >Mkt/Industry structure -.301, .284, -1.048 v4,vl Economic Env------>Market Potential .434, .221, 1.807 v4,v2 Regulation--—-->Market Potential -.454, .231, -1.805 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure ->Market Potential -. 180, .234, -.713 v5,v4 Market Potential-«-»->Incoming foreign invst .582, .259, 2.374 v6,v4 Market Potential----->Globa1 Diffusion -.104, .137, -.905 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst--—--->Global Diffusion .034, .129, .297 v6,v7 Global Innovation------>Global Diffusion .946, .102, 10.088 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 9,636,12 p-value .647 BBFI 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 v1= gnp, v2= pricereg, v3= indconc, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 194 Table B.4 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value v3,vl Economic env >Mkt/Industry structure -.332, .252, -1.306 v3 ,v2 . Regulation >Mkt/Industry structure .476, .252, 1.928 v4,vl Economic Env ->Market Potential .721, .231, 3.092 v4,v2 Regulation—«m->Market Potential -.081, .249, -.321 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure---«->Market Potential .442, .257, 1.668 v5,v4 Market Potential----—>Incoming foreign invst .61 1, .240, 2.561 v6,v4 Market Potential-—---->Globa1 Diffusion -.1 12, . 130, -.949 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst-—--->Global Diffusion .035, .129, .297 v6,v7 Global Innovation--««-->Global Diffusion .946, .102, 10.090 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 6.426, 12 p-value .893 BBFI .990 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 v1= gnp, v2= apptime, v3= indfocus, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 195 Table B.5 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value v3,vl Economic env- >Mkt/Industry structure -.197, .281, -.706 v3,v2 Regulation >Mkt/Industry structure .329, .281, 1.180 v4,v1 Economic Env ->Market Potential .570, .246, 2.299 v4,v2 Regulation-~—-->Market Potential .144, .255, .558 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure---->Market Potential -.042, .258, -.161 v5,v4 Market Potentia1-—--->Incoming foreign invst .61 l, .240, 2.561 v6,v4 Market Potential ->Global Diffusion -. 1 39, . 130, - 1 .216 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst---->Globa1 Diffusion .037, .129, .323 v6,v7 Global Innovation- ->Globa1 Diffusion .946, .102, 10.441 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 7.848,12 p—value .796 BBFI .990 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 v1= gnp, v2= apptime, v3= indgrwth, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 196 Table B.6 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value Economic envu-uzi’lt‘ilit/Indusuy structure .225, .293, .768 Regulation :iril‘d/zlndusn'y structure .033, .293, .1 13 Economic Env—ZillMarket Potential .597, .246, 2.405 Regutauon—u-V-iéiiarkct Potential .132, .240, .548 Mkt/Industry suucmieili>Market Potential -.081, .246, -.325 Market Potentialm-Y-S-gntoming foreign invst .61 1, .240, 2.561 Market Potenfial-fiiGlobal Diffusion -.147, .130, -1.298 Incoming foreign inJSiS-ii—filobal Diffusion .038, .129, .331 V 6 , V 7 Global Innovation-—-->Global Diffusion .946, .102, 10.551 Fit Indices Chi-square, df p—value BBFI BBNFI CFI 8265,12 .764 1.000 1.000 1.000 v1= gnp, v2= apptime, v3= indconc, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 197 Table B.7 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value v3,vl Economic env >Mkt/Industry structure .502, .250, 2.455 v3,v2 Regulation >Mkt/Industry structure .536, .250, 2.618 v4,vl Economic Env----->Market Potential 1.002, .067, 15.281 v4,v2 Regulation-~-->Market Potential .054, .069, .81 1 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure--—->Market Potential -.036, .065, -.461 v5,v4 Market Potential----->Incoming foreign invst .623, .233, 2.641 V6,V4 Market Potential---—->Global Diffusion —.134, .127, - l . 147 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst----->Global Diffusion .037, .129, .314 v6,v7 Global Innovation—--—-->Global Diffusion .946, .102, 10.322 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 9.387, 12 p-value .669 BBFI 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 v1= pop, v2= pricereg, v3= infocus, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 198 Table B.8 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value v3,vl Economic env >Mkt/Industry structure -.087, .296, .297 v3,v2 Regulation---->Mkt/Indust1y suucmre .233, .296, .797 v4,vl Economic Emma-«>Market Potential .987, .053, 18.880 v4,v2 Regulation---—->Market Potential .044, .055, .821 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure»-—-->Market Potential -.037, .054, -.695 v5,v4 Market Potential----->Incoming foreign invst .623, .233, 2.641 V6,V4 Market Potential >Global Diffusion -.131, .127, -1.1 19 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst—--->Global Diffusion .037, .129, .311 ‘ v6,v7 Global Innovation--~—>Global Diffusion .946, .102, 10.285 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 8.13 1,12 p-value .774 BBFI 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 vl= pop, v2= pricereg, v3= indgrwth, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 199 Table 13.9 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coeffiiients, Standard error, t-filue v3,vl Economic env >Mkt/Industry structure -.304, .273, -l.233 v3,v2 Regulation >Mkt/Industry structure -.488, .273, -l.979 v4,vl Economic Env----.>Market Potential 1.016, .050, 20.656 v4,v2 Regulation---->Market Potential .088, .055, 1.633 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure~-—>Market Potential .107, .052, 1.906 v5,v4 Market Potential--—--->Incoming foreign invst .623, .233, 2.641 V6,V4 Market Potential———-->Global Diffusion -. 134, .127, -l.146 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst----—>Global Diffusion .037, .129, .314 v6,v7 Global Innovation—---—->Globa1 Diffusion .946, .102, 10.326 Fit Tndices Chi-square, df 9724,12 p-value .6401 BBFI 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 v1= pop, v2= pricereg, v3= indconc, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 200 Table B.10 Global Diffusion Model fiths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value Economic envum:3>1\‘111vlndusuy structure .138, .267, .511 Regulation :mdmny structure .423, .267, 1.569 Economic Env—V4’Y>1Market Potential .986, .055, 17.856 Regulanonmzéiiaikei Potential .032, .060, .532 Mkt/Industry snucm‘iiifmmmei Potential -.020, .061, -.321 Market remnaniinionnng foreign invst .613, .239, 2.574 Market Poientiailflgciobai Diffusion -.148, .129, -1.305 Incoming foreign invvsgii-ociobai Diffusion .038, .129, .331 v6,v7 Global Innovationu- ----- >Global Diffusion .946, .102, 10.547 Fit Indices Chi-square, df p-value BBFI BBNFI CFI 6.223.12 .904 1.000 1.000 1.000 vl= pop, v2= apptime, v3= indfocus, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 201 Table B.11 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coaficients, Smlfiard error, t-value Economic env V3>1t‘rilh/Industty structure -.115, .285, -.406 Regulation :mt/zlndmw structure .325, .285, 1.148 Economic Env—flgMarket Potential .978, .054, 18.176 Regulation—«ggdzarket Potential .038, .056, .672 Mkt/Industry sn'ucmvrg’vs >Market Potential -.044, .056, -.765 Market Pomnun-uugéirionung foreign invst .613, .239, 2.574 Market Potential V6’V:Global Diffusion -.149, .129, -1.297 Incoming foreign in:s:::-5-—>Global Diffusion .038, .129, .330 v6,v7 Global Innovation---->Global Diffusion .945, .102, 10.405 F-it Indices Chi-square, df p-value BBFI BBNFI CFI 6.753,12 .873 1.000 1.000 1.000 v1= pop, v2= apptime, v3= indgrwth, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat 202 Table B.12 Global Diffusion Model Paths Coefficients, Standard error, t-value v3,vl Economic env----->Mkt/Industry structure -.017, .301, -.057 v3,v2 Regulation-«~«->Mkt/Industry structure .065, .301, .215 v4,v1 Economic Env---«->Market Potential .984, .051, 19.360 v4,v2 Regulation- >Market Potential .019, .051, .381 v4,v3 Mkt/Industry structure—--->Market Potential .068, .051, 1.339 v5,v4 Market Potential ----- ->Incoming foreign invst .613, .239, 2.574 V6,V4 Market Potential ----- >Global Diffusion -. 1 5 3, .129, -1.341 v6,v5 Incoming foreign invst ----- >Global Diffusion .038, .129, .335 v6,v7 Global Innovation-—---->Global Diffusion .945, .102, 10.460 Fit Indices Chi-square, df 7.107.12 p-value .8504 BBFI 1.000 BBNFI 1.000 CFI 1.000 v1= pop, v2= apptime, v3= indconc, v4=mktpot, v5=infrgn, v6=diff, v7=innovat HICHIG m.» 11111111111111“