)V1ESI.J RETURNING MATERIALS: Place in book drop to LIBRARJES remove this checkout from .—_. your record. FINES will » be charged if book is returned after the date stamped below. AMERICAN IDEOLOGIES AND SENATORIAL VOTING RECORDS BY Gregory Michael Browne A THESIS Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF ARTS Department of History 1984 of: is J and CORE ofc theO reco SUPP and ABSTRACT AMERICAN IDEOLOGIES AND SENATORIAL VOTING RECORDS By Gregory Michael Browne I believe that the conventional ideological classification of Americans into "conservatives" and "liberals" is inadequate. What is required is a classification with several degrees of conservatism and liberalism, and additional dimensions as well. Therefore I constructed a more complex classification, with several cate- gories and two main dimensions, building upon some classifications of others and upon my own ideas. I wished to see some systematic evidence to support my theories. Therefore I tested them by examining Senatorial voting records from 1959 to 1978. For the sake of making the investigation manageable, the classifications and the voting study dealt with only one issue area--that of economics, which seemed the most important. The result of this examination was to find moderate to strong support for all major cleavages between the categories of my model, and for other cleavages also. This thesis is dedicated to my parents, Mr. and Mrs. Joseph (Alvina) Browne. ii ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to acknowledge all of the help I received in writing this thesis from my parents, Mr. and Mrs. Joseph (Alvina) Browne. In addition to raising me and paying for my education, they have provided me with a home and support while I composed the thesis, paid for the course fees and other fees necessary for my getting credit for it, and put up with my work habits for a long time. Also, to my father belongs credit for drawing the diagrams. iii TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES. . . . . . . . . LIST OF FIGURES . . . . . . . . IINTRODUCTION . . . . . . . . . (IHAPTER I II 1311 THE CLASSIFICATION. . . . METHODOIIOGY O O O O O 0 Historical Background. . TESTING THE MODEL: AN ANALYSIS RECORDS . . . . . . . Introduction. . . . . Survey of Voting Records. Introduction. . . . Income Taxes. . . . Tariff Issues . . . General Spending . . Revenue Sharing . . . Public Works. . . . Social Security. . . Labor Issues. . . . Food Stamps . . . . Aid to Families with Depedent (W) o o o o 0 Housing . . . . . Education. . . . . THE VOTING CEO and other poverty programs. . . . Labor and HEW Departmental Funds . . . Mass Transit. . . . Government Aid to Business . Wage and Price Controls . Fuel Rationing and Related Programs . . Federal Energy Administration (PEA) . . No-Fault Insurance. . Anti'tI'USt Law 0 o 0 iv 48 67 86 86 144 144 147 151 152 154 155 160 161 170 171 172 174 177 181 182 183 185 186 187 188 188 CHAPTER Page Airline Deregulation. . . . . . . . 188 Consumer Protection . . . . . . . . 189 National Consumer Co-operative Bank. . . 190 Occupational Safety and Health Administra- tion (OSHA). . . . . . . . . . 191 Environmental Issues. . . . . . . . 192 Correspondences Between the Cleavages From the Voting Records and The Cleavages From the Theoretical Mbdel . . . . . . . 198 Groups Produced By the Cleavages, and Their Correspondences to Categories From the Theoretical Model. . . . . . . . . 207 A Special Problem: The Place of the Southern Democrats . . . . . . . . . . . 215 Cleavage Sets From the Voting Records Which Do Not Correspond to Cleavages From the MOdel. O O O O O O O O O O O O 219 IV CONCLUSION . . . . . . . . . . . . . 228 BIBLIOGRAPHY................237 LIST OF TABLES Votes Used. . . . . . . . . . . . Roll-Call Votes . . . . . . . . . . Aggregations of Cleavages (Cleavage Sets) . Summary of Correspondences Between Cleavages From.Voting Records and Cleavages From the Theoretical Model . . . . . . . . Groups Produced By Cleavages From the Voting Records and Their Correspondences With the Categories of the Theoretical Model . . vi 102 199 206 207 FIGURE J10 211 112 213 114 155 lfi 317 :18 LIST OF FIGURES Liberals and Conservatives. . . . . . . The Left-Right Dimension . . . . . . . Attitudes toward equality . . . . . . . Equality and government intervention . . . European ideologies . . . . . . . . . Attitudes toward equality in Europe. . . . . The triangular scheme . . . . . . . . The equality and liberty dimensions. The distribution of ideologies in Europe . . . The distribution of ideologies in the U.S.A.. The Hofstadter model (with extrapolations) . The Weinstein model . . . . . . . . . . The Weinstein model, and the liberty and equality dimensions . . . . . . . . . . . . . The modified Weinstein model and the triangular SCheme O O O O O I O O O I O O O 0 Further modifications of the Weinstein model and the triangular scheme . . . . . . . . . Further modifications of the Weinstein model and the triangular scheme (continued) . . . . . Further modifications of the Weinstein model and the triangular scheme (continued) . . . . . The modified Weinstein model partially integrated with the Hofstadter model . . . . . . . vii ll 12 15 15 18 19 22 23 24 24 25 26 FIGURE Page 19 Further integration of the Hofstadter and Weinstein models: the rightism of the radical progressives. . 28 20 The extreme leftism of the radical progressives . . 29 21 The rightism and leftism of the radical progressives. 29 22 Simplification of Figure 21 . . . . . . . . . 30 23 The New Deal Era: integration of the Patterson and Feinman categories into model . . . . . . . . 33 24 Rightist (Republican) New Dealers . . . . . . . 38 25 The Anti-Statist row extended leftward . . . . . 39 26 Degrees of Statism . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 27 The New Deal versus Great Society liberalism . . . 43 viii INTRODUCTION The importance of making an ideological classification of the participants in our political process has been recognized over the years by various people who have created typologies in the attempt to fit political actions into them. However, most of these classi— fications were simple, with only two, three or four categories, all on one dimension. Consequently, many important figures do not fit into them or fit rather poorly. This is taken by many to suggest that there is not sufficient evidence of patterns in political attitudes to warrant a classification, beyond noting "right" and "left" poles on an axis, with people located at various points along it. Yet what needs to be considered is whether a more elaborate and subtle classification could compensate for the inadequacies in existing typologies. We contend in this thesis that such a classi- fication can be made, and that it takes the form which will subse- quently be outlined. We will then test its meaningfulness by attempt- ing to fit it to current politics by examining Senatorial voting records. Therefore, this paper will present the proposed new classi- fication and then test it by examining voting records in recent decades. The first part will be based mainly on the reading of secondary sources, including the typologies of others, while the second part will be based mainly on voting records, a kind of pri- mary source. This paper will have to put some restraints on its focus in order to be of manageable scope. It was decided to focus on only one issue area, and economics was chosen as the issue area. It was selected because economics is rather basic ideologically; that is, ideologies often derive their stands on other issues from their stands on economic issues. We will elaborate further on this later. The Senate was selected because it is a more manageable body on which to do a voting study than is the House of Representatives, which is the only real alternative body to study, if one wishes to do a voting study of national politics. The time frame for the analysis of the voting records also needed to have limits. The slice of time from 1959 to 1978 was selected because twenty years seemed to be the greatest length that such a survey could be and still fit within the proposed scope of this paper; and that particular twenty-year period seemed to encompass the most interesting changes in the recent past. The first chapter of this thesis will present the proposed classification. It will examine conventional American and European classifications, and typologies of Progressive Era politics (notably those proposed by Richard Hofstadter and James Weinstein), of New Deal politics, and of the Great Society era (especially that pro- posed by Kevin Phillips), and related matters. As we proceed, a classification will be sketched out. It will have two main dimensions: c} t} bi ed th an 811 to one involving equalitarianism and inegalitarianism and the other involving libertarianism (individualism) and statism (collectivism). Distinctions will be made between the liberalisms of the New Deal, of the Great Society and of the Progressive Era, as well as between (modern) liberalism, classical liberalism (modern conservatism) and traditionalist conservatism. The second chapter will explain the methodology of the analysis of the voting records. It will also include sections on the historical background period to be examined. In the third chapter, the analysis itself will be done. First, we will summarize the votes by issue area, and then aggregate the cleavages produced by the votes into larger cleavages. Second, we will attempt to find correspondences between the cleavages and those of the model. Third, we will see into what groups the aggregate cleavages divide the Senators, and then find the correspondences between the groups and the categories of the model. Finally, the fourth chapter will summarize the paper and discuss applications of this kind of work to other subjects. pr Fi Bu CO‘ Pi Am 01' CHAPTER I THE CLASSIFICATION The ideological classification of politicians in use in the press and in ordinary classification does not usually go beyond the "conservative-liberal" or "right-left" scheme. Sometimes, this is a simple dichotomy of conservatives (rightists) and liberals (leftists) (see Figure 1). ( Conservative 9 Figure l.--Liberals and Conservatives. But right and left are directions on a dimension, thus implying a continuum (see Figure 2). Liberals Conservatives +——(Left) (Right)-——+ Figure 2.--The Left-Right Dimension. And so people are generally described as more or less conservative or liberal, more or less "rightist" or "leftist". Or they are IE th 1i eq F1 al- to described as being somewhere between conservative and liberal, as moderates (or moderate-conservatives or moderate-liberals), or as somewhere in the center (or on the center-right or the center-left). Various definitions of these terms are given. Nonetheless, there exists (at least in regard to economic matters, with which we shall be concerned here) pretty close agreement on.what these types mean, at least in the actual practice of classification. The more liberal or "to the left" one is, the more one favors the use of government to make the members of society more equal, at least in regard to wealth or economic power; the more conservative or "to the right" one is, the more one opposes doing this. The (relative) liberal or leftist thus supports the use of government to move toward equality; the (relative) conservative or rightist opposes this1 (see Figure 3). Liberal Conservative +——(Left) (Right)-—+ +——-egalitarian inegalitarian——+ Figure 3.--Attitudes toward equality. There is some ambiguity as to what it is about the liberal (left) goals that the conservative (rightist) opposes. It is not always clear whether conservatives are simply all of those opposed to liberal egalitarianism (see Figure 2 again) or are, in addition, Fi Fi people who oppose the principle of government intervention (espe- cially in the economy) whether for egalitarian purposes or not (see Figure 4). /////2( against Con:::v::ives Government 8 intervention Liberals for ’(/,/// (Left) 1 +—-egalitarian Equality inegalitarian -+ Figure 4.--Equality and government intervention. This classification is a simplification of the prevailing classification of ideologies applied in Europe, and commonly used in the study of political philosophy as well. The principal cate- gories are as follows: traditional conservatism (traditionalism), classical liberalism, and socialism, with the addition of modern liberalism as a transition or hybrid between classical liberalism and socialism (see Figure 5). //<><2/;/;//4 uéaéEHI/ /cia§aie£iW Tradifignalism Socialism/////Liberalism// Liberalism/ (Traditional’ 1 /// ///// ////// //// “ls/89% 3}“) Figure 5.--European ideologies. Fi I10 (1“ fc t} of (t t1 WE be it The resulting sequence (traditionalism—-classical liberalism-dmodern liberalisme-socialism) also represents the ranking of the philoso- phies in terms of their egalitarianism, from least to most (see Figure 6). In general, from the time of the decline of the feudal / I / l / / / / / ///// Modern // / Classica // Traditiona Socialism ’//’Liberalism/ Liberalism Conservatism / l I / // //// +——-Egalitaria////1///’ //<:;:;/// Inegal ita gr [// //1/4;/ / Figure 6.--Attitudes toward equality in Europe. nobility until at least the nineteenth century, the more inegalitarian a group was, the more it supported its country's king, so that traditionalist conservatives were his strongest supporters. There- fore, in European parliaments of this period, the speaker (who was the representative of the king) saw to it that the more supportive of the king a party was, the farther it sat to the speaker's right (the position of honor); the less supportive it was, the further to the left it sat. Thus, the order presented above, which initially was roughly reflective of the degree of support for the monarchy, became a right-to-left order. And since this order was already one of inegalitarianism to egalitarianism, "right" and "left" came to imply these respective attitudes. The traditionalist supporters of royalty and aristocracy were, at first, in the position of defending the established powers and trying to preserve the status quo. They were hence known as CE WE C5 pa pl tri 80‘ SUI pa fo- th we Va We "conservatives". Their principal opponents were what were then called liberals, and now called classical liberals (the other kind of liberal being rare before the late nineteenth century). Conse- quently, "conservative" came to be used as a synonym for rightist and inegalitarian, and "liberal" came to be used as a partial synonym for leftist and egalitarian. What is called modern liberalism arose in the late nineteenth century, accepting many socialist measures (especially in social welfare) without being willing to abandon liberalism (including its capitalistic economic principles) altogether. This philosophy was partially liberal (in the classical liberal sense) in the first place, and further strengthened its claim to the liberal title by transforming the meaning of "liberalism" itself from freedom from government to freedom from economic and social restraints in general, such as freedom from want. And since "liberalism" had already become partially synonymous with egalitarianism, modern liberalism there- fore was able to paradoxically say that it was more "liberal" than (classical) liberalism, and eventually, at least in the United States, the only liberalism. Moreover, traditionalism in this country was weak and classical liberalism, later joined by modern liberalism, was strong. Consequently, the terms conservatism and liberalism were not much used for a long time, and this made it easier for modern liberalism to appropriate exclusive title to the term "liberalism". Meanwhile, classical liberalism, as the more rightist (and less "libera1) of the two major philosophies, came to be called "conservatism”.2 (n -y ea de pc DC in SO 51 cai It Eq' la‘. la‘ 88 Du hi St "Traditionalism" is the term applied to the dominant social structure in European society through the end of the Middle Ages and early modern times, and throughout much of the rest of the world until the time of Western colonization and beyond. This broad category includes tribal society, kingdoms and empires, absolute monarchies and decentralized feudal regimes. Traditionalism is here defined as a value-system which upholds an inequality--a legal- political one as well as an economic one--which involves a hereditary, more-or-less fixed and closed class system, whose origins were often in brute force, but whose justification was made on the basis of some innate superiority of blood or some mystic sanction. All slavery and serfdom thus partake of traditionalism. "Classical liberalism" refers to the philosophy which advo- cates liberty from government, as typified by that of John Locke. It says that all individuals possess certain natural moral rights equally. These include the right to one's own labor and what the labor produces (including what one withdraws from nature by this labor). It is an injustice to violate these rights; government is set up to protect these rights and has no right to violate them. These principles may be taken in their most extreme form to mandate pure laissez-faire, as the modern Libertarian Party would do, but many who are called classical liberals (including, it seems, Locke himself) would depart from it in many particular instances while still adhering to the general principle. Generally similar ideas have been advocated by others of this group, such as the British W . . Dal C01 801 di: 0Y1 qu in gi SC di 81 1'6 10 Whigs, Adam Smith, most of our "Founding Fathers", the Social Darwinists, and, to some extent, John Stuart Mill. "Socialism" refers to these philosophies which through common (and presumably democratic) ownership (or at least control) of wealth or the sources of wealth aim to achieve a more—or-less equal distribution of wealth, and so achieve equality of condition. Var- ious forms of socialism have been advocated by the likes of Robert Owen, Fourier, Marx, Saint-Simon and the Fabians. In short, traditionalism upholds unequal chances to be wealthy (or perhaps better, unequal certainties); classical liberal— ism favors an equal liberty to achieve unequal wealth or economic condition; socialism seeks equality of economic condition. Another, somewhat different (probably less accurate) way of approaching the distinctions is to say that traditionalism defends inequality based on the class into which one was born (which rests ultimately on con- quest, racial origin or religious sanction); while capitalism defends inequality based primarily on merit and effort (and inheritance and gift from those who earned it by their merit and effort); and socialism opposes both kinds of inequality. Modern liberalism would move society to some degree in the direction of equality of condition, while stopping short of socialism and complete egalitarianism. We may now make use of the conceptual scheme of some thinkers, such as F. A. Hayek,3 who think of the three main ideologies as representing a triangular scheme with one at each corner, and with sci r1, di] ta 31' SO es Vi fr in Dr th ti 81: to 11 modern liberalism on the side between classical liberalism and socialism (see Figure 7). But triangularity implies two- WClassic LiberalisD Modern Liberalism Traditional Socialism \Eonservatism Figure 7.-—The triangular scheme. dimensionality. And the study of political philosophy does indeed make another distinction: classical liberalism is termed "liber- tarian" (or "individualist") while both socialism and traditionalism are called "statist" (or "collectivist") (with modern liberalism somewhere in between). That is, the former opposes "big government" (much government restriction of the liberty of the individual), especially government intervention in the economy, seeing it as a violation of his rights, while the latter two favor it. This follows from their goals: classical liberalism wishes to abolish traditional inequalities (castes, slavery, etc.) and any others that are the product of government force, but wishes to preserve inequalities that arise from the "natural" (non-governmental) processes of produc- tion and trade (with the only natural routes to inequality to be stamped out being private force and fraud), whereas socialism wishes to use government to impose an equality (of condition) upon man and BE t0 ti 80 0U ta ta (5 12 traditionalism.wishes to impose an inequality on them (both of which are, from the classical liberal viewpoint, unnatural). In any case, socialist equality and traditionalist inequality both require govern- ment interference with "natural" economic processes (if only the toleration of some men using force to enslave others, which tolera- tion changes an anarchic violence into government violence, since a government, as such, must monopolize violence, and therefore either outlaw it or assume responsibility for it). We now have two dimensions: inegalitarianism versus egali- tarianism (which can be called the "equality dimension") and liber- tarianism versus statism (which can be called the "liberty dimension") (see Figure 8). f Classical libertarian Liberalism Liberty Modern Liberalism statist Socialism \ Traditional 1 \ Conservatism.) +-egalitarian Equality inegalitarian —+ Figure 8.--The equality and liberty dimensions. (At this point, we should note that it is a logical con- clusion that any departure from pure classical liberalism--that is, laissez-faire--to the right, left or any other direction, necessarily 13 requires the increase of state power, and so is a move toward statism. Consequently, in the charts and discussion, the "liberty dimension" will measure only that statism which is ngt_the product of egalitarianism or inegalitarianism.) Taking account of this two-dimensionality helps us to explain the ambiguity in the American usage of the term "conservatism", noted above. When the term is identified with inegalitarianism, then it includes traditionalism as well as classical liberalism (plus as that statism which would fall in the center on the equality dimension, directly below classical liberalism); both of which stand for inegalitarian opposition to modern liberalism's striving for equality of condition. However, when conservatism is used as a synonym for classical liberalism, then it implies opposition to statism, as well as to equality (of condition). To summarize the preceding discussion, we can say that we now have two dimensions. The first is the inegalitarian--egalitarian one (the equality dimension). This is what is usually called the right-left dimension; the former is the equivalent of conservatism; the latter, in this country, is the partial equivalent of liberalism. The second dimension is the libertarian-statist (individualist- collectivist) one (the liberty dimension). On the equality dimension, the arrangement of the ideologies from right to left is as follows: traditionalism, classical liberal- ism, modern liberalism and socialism. On the liberty dimension, classical liberalism is at the libertarian end of the scale, socj liba soci to 1 Sir! diag more that the ( Amer: ineg; Euro; 0the of t POIt the the the and Pra it of a8 Dre l4 socialism and traditionalism are at the statist end, and modern liberalism is in the middle. From this discussion, we can see that socialism and traditionalism are weak in the United States, relative to their condition in Europe. Conversely, classical liberalism is strong here, relative to its condition in Europe. In terms of the diagram, the political culture of the United States is distributed more toward the libertarian end of the liberty dimension than is that of Europe, and is distributed more tightly around the center on the equality dimension4 (see Figures 9 and 10). Hence, when an American is referred to herein as a statist, an egalitarian or an inegalitarian, these terms are used in the American rather than the European context, and so imply less extreme positions than they otherwise would. The South presents a special problem. The political position of the bulk of Southern politicians in this century was one of sup- port for the white supremacist regime which was set up in most of the South in 18903 and which collapsed in the 19505 and 19605 under the impact of the "civil rights" movement. This regime was based on the disfranchisement, by the poll-tax and other means, of most blacks, and many poor whites as well. It was racist, and since racism in practice is a form of inequality based on ascriptive characteristics, it partook of traditionalism to this extent. The disfranchisement of the poor whites was, to some extent, a symptom of economic elitism as well; how much it was, and how much this elitism is to be inter- preted as a sign of traditionalist ideology is a matter of dispute.5 15 .<.m.= men a“ moawonomefi no coausnaunmae m;au-.oH unamam Ema:¢eu«afiameCH Seacoaumufiamww IIIIIIIIIIIIIIVHHAummcoo Emwamfiuom Hmaofiuaemua . .5 .o-uvu...hH. emaamuasaa . cwowoz saw awanmwmaao Hmowmmmfiu .<.m.: .onouom cw monOHoovH mo cowusnauumfiv m£H||.a muomfim achMHpmuHHmwoafi EmasmHHMufiHmwo .fi +IIIIIIIIIIIII>HHAuwmaou EmmHMHoom HmaOHuHowuH MWW EmauMum ..? $.35qu Emwamuonfiq HmUHmmeu Emficmfiumuumnfia MAOMDM cla 53?. egal and Thes the 1962 One one 30c. 30r. to . Pug inc the 16 There are further possibilities for elaboration of the classification beyond the triangular scheme presented above. There is reason to believe that there is more than one type of modern liberalism. At the very least, it would seem likely from the model that there are different degrees of "leftism"--that is, there could be forms of modern liberalism close to classical liberalism, which pass through various intermediate steps to a form which is close to socialism. And perhaps one could perceive several meaningful incre- ments of this leftism. It should be borne in mind that in the twentieth century there have been in this country three major periods of modern liberal legislation on the national level. That is to say, there have been three major legislative agendas that brandish egalitarian slogans and claim to benefit classes other than business and the rich, usually at the expense of the latter two groups. These were the programs of the Progressive Era (circa 1901—1920), the New Deal (circa 1933-1939) and the Great Society (circa 1965— 1968). Each one increased the size of government: each successive one increased Federal spending to a higher level than the previous one, and thereby increased the burden of paying for it. (The Great Society, in the sense of the Johnson-era programs and their succes- sors, was not accompanied by a great rise in tax rates, but it led to deficits which fueled inflation, which is a sort of tax, and pushed people into higher tax brackets-—"bracket creep"--which increased the tax burden.) It seems to make sense to think that there would be some who would favor one program but oppose the next, 17 more extensive one. The same could apply to the stages in the development of these programs--as, for example, the early and late (or "First" and "Second") New Deals. We begin with the Progressive Era (circa 1901-1920). At first examination, the conflicts of this era seem much like contem- porary ones to us, with "(modern) liberal" progressives proposing to expand government for the sake of equality, and their "conservative" (classical liberal) opponents resisting.6 However, there are quali- fications to be made to this simple scheme. The first for us to consider is that made by Richard Hofstadter in The Age of Reform. There he argued that the average progressive politician represented the petit-bourgeois small busi- nessman (or his agrarian counterpart, the yeoman farmer), and that his political attitudes followed suit. He was not as far left as later (New Deal and post-New Deal) liberals; distrusting the "work- ing class" (i.e., manual laborers) in general and trade unions in particular, he was not a strong advocate of labor legislation, or, for that matter, of the welfare state, and might have become a strong opponent of these if he had lived long enough7 (see Figure 11). Further, he was also distinguishable from latter-day liberals on the liberty dimension as well as on the equality dimension, in his yearn- ing for the classical liberal ideals of competition and, to a lesser extent, small government.8 Other historians of this era, such as James Weinstein, have advanced the concept of "corporate liberalism". This is a form of 8 l +|III Asmaumufimwmed $on muonaooawq owumg Aamaoauwomuhv mo>aum>umm=ou fioammeH gum 3m A.nHA .mmmaov mo>fium>uomcoo .Aw=0fiumaoamuuxm £ua3v Hence pmuomumwom oSHII.Ha unawam whoenmm fiasco» can .mamcoammmwoum .omsmmocwmam Hamam mw>Hmmmuwoum Acmfiumufiamwov ammu.lllliv Anneaoo GH .amov Honda umaaouuosam Aammn 3oz uwom Emwamfluom van Home 3ozv amfiamuonaq .8qu fl mszmmZOU .m.: (mode busin sions under If so hurt prote expa: Many tryin VEins OPhy, mEdie men ( their as it 1 35 RC NE04 (Layc (3:33] SOCI: Figur l9 (modern) liberalism, which was enunciated or at least supported by businessmen, who thought that they could benefit from liberal exten- sions of government power, such as business regulation, especially under the Federal Trade Commission and other regulatory commissions.9 If such regulations hurt a businessman's competitors more than they hurt him, he stood to benefit. Regulations against price-cutting protect an established business against the newcomer trying to expand his market by undercutting the prices of the competition. Many other regulations are harder to bear for the small newcomer trying to grow than for the established big business. In his The Corporate Ideal and the Liberal State 1900-1918,10 Weinstein also notes that exponents of the corporate liberal philos~ ophy, such as the National Civic Federation, saw themselves as inter- mediate between the conservative, old—style (mostly small) business- men (represented by the National Association of Manufacturers), and their opponents on the left. weinstein identified these "leftists" as including not only the socialists, but also "neo-populists" such as Robert LaFollette (see Figure 12). LaFollette wished to break NEO-POPULISTS (LaFollette, etc.) (Small Business, etc.) \ CORPORATE CONSERVATIVES LIBERALS -——____ (N.A,M.) (N.C.F. - Big Business) (Small Busi- ness) SOCIALISTS +——-—- LEFT RIGHT-———~+ Figure 12.--The Weinstein model. the str: hig} LaFL busi nati redL the fur Era Ins th' Th 11 he CO Ca he D} it Cc 20 the power of big business in order to restore free competition. A strict or literal interpretation of the Sherman Antitrust Act and high taxes (mainly personal income taxes on large fortunes, because LaFollette opposed corporate income taxes as being harmful to small businesses) were tools he proposed using (he even contemplated nationalization, which, though not furthering competition, would reduce the power of big business). LaFollette, although placed on the left in the Weinstein scheme, did resemble the conservatives of the NAM, in his wish to protect the interests of small business and further competition, as Weinstein himself notes. A further wrinkle is added to this picture of Progressive Era politics by David Thelen in his study Robert LaFollette and the Insurgent Spiri£.11 Here, LaFollette is shown as beginning his political career with a strong confidence in the self-made man and the American system of competition which allowed this man to rise. These attitudes were naturally associated with conservative (classical liberal) political attitudes, and such were the attitudes that he held at the start of his political career. The apparent decline of competition and increase of concentration in business constituted the catalyst that led to his later more radical political views. Yet he seems to have seen no revolutionary change in his political philosophy, and there apparently was none. LaFollette thus seems to share with the NAM conservatives not only their small business constituency but also a fondness, on balance, for the ideals of free market competition. sir em; me: of pra 1'68 fou Sim we ] taxe Vat: res; One bus: res; tri: to c: app»: of ( fan: “‘4 21 At this point, we can see that LaFollette‘s view 100kS similar to that of another "radical" politician of his time--William Jennings Bryan. As was LaFollette, Bryan was an admirer of self- employed people, although it was farmers rather than small business- men that were his chief concern; also like LaFollette he was a lover of relatively individualistic competition, approximately as it was practiced in the nineteenth century, and he supported radical measures in the antitrust and other fields, chiefly in order to restore the competitive marketplace. From this reading of Weinstein and Thelen, a two-dimensional, four-category scheme of ideological classification for the Progres- sive Era emerges. On the side of competition and small businessmen we have two groups, one "conservative" and the other "radical"--on taxes, nationalization and big business generally--the NAM conser- vatives and the "neo-populists" such as LaFollette and Bryan, respectively. On the side of concentration we again have two groups, one conservative and one radical on taxes, nationalization and big business generally--the corporate liberals and the socialists respectively (see Figure 13). This four-category scheme is two-dimensional, as was the triangular one, and suggests it. The competitive dimension appears to correspond to the liberty dimension, whereas the other dimension appears to correspond to the equality dimension. The conservatives, of course, are classical liberals, and the socialists are also familiar to us. The "corporate liberals" seem to be statists of the 22 k 1' i A.uum .oemv umafiowm onHHHmmzoo A.oum .wofiumsoluwauav HOL iaanllll. unwmu coaumuaamwmcfi NHHAwum>ummcou muoaumm amaomw pom mommonamam Hamam n.0uo cm>am .muuoaaommqv mumwasaom can mumfiaamomlooz ummH .mcowmaOEav huwamsvo pow hunonfia ecu pom .Hoooa cfioumafioz onyll.ma muowfim omfiumuflamwo IIIIIily a umfiumum VHmmmHA SGHHmunn—HH cent betw neo- posi Figu this and 23 center--no farther left, or right, than the classical liberals-- between the traditionalists and the socialists. The populists and nee-populists represented by Bryan and LaFollette represent a new position, one which is egalitarian and libertarian (see Figure 14). Classical Liberalism Neo-Pop. V/7. Cons. l///JV/S::. Corp. Lib. - Traditionalism Figure 14--—The modified Weinstein model and the triangular scheme. However, this tends to overstate the case. As we will see, this last group is not necessarily egalitarian by modern (New Deal and post-New Deal) standards in regard to social welfare measures. Thus it is not as far left as the socialists are. Then again, it tends to support many of the statist measures of a "progressive" nature favored by corporate liberals, such as the FTC and anti-price cutting measures.13 Therefore it is not as libertarian as at least some conservatives. The resulting fact that it is only moderately libertarian and only moderately egalitarian fits this LaFollette-Bryan group in better with the triangular scheme (see Figure 15). Fig For Sta-f thr: tra: 24 Cons. Neo- Pop. ,////// Soc. Corp. Lib. 1 Figure 15.--Further modifications of the Weinstein model and the triangular scheme. It seems that the four-category scheme needs elaboration. For one thing, the socialists are considerably more egalitarian and statist than the members, or most of them, in each of these other three groups. They are about as far removed from them as are the traditionalists (see Figure 16). A ////// Cons. I Neo- / Pop. Corp. Lib. ah—_____ Soc. I | Trad. Figure l6.-Further modifications of the Weinstein model and the triangular scheme (continued). Fig the 5.1 Fi COD' meag bUSt dimfi La, and 25 This leaves a gap in the statist-egalitarian quadrant of Figure 13. Still, it is possible that there is a group similar to the Bryan-LaFollette group on the equality dimension, but more /\ statist (see Figure 17). / Cons . 7. . Neo- Pop. / ? Corp. Lib. Soc. Trad. Figure l7.--Further modifications of the Weinstein model and the triangular scheme (continued). We now seem to have integrated Weinstein's typology into the conventional classification scheme. At this point, it seems we can say that since some of the measures advanced by the LaFollette-Bryan group (radical trust- busting and some nationalization) seem to be extremely leftist even by today‘s standards, we actually have,with respect to the equality dimension, two columns: an extreme left column (including the LaFollette-Bryan group) and a column more to the right (conservatives and corporate liberals). Roi Elf. Pi 26 What of those on the moderate left: what of the bulk of Hofstadter's progressives? A column should be set up here in the middle, embracing libertarian and statist divisions (see Figure 18). Hofstadter Progressives (Left) Extreme Center Right Left Left Cons. Anti-Statist Neo-Pop and Populist Hoover Progressive Statists ("Corporate Liberals") Statist Beveridge Wood Figure l8.--The modified Weinstein model partially integrated with the Hofstadter model. The libertarian division of the center-left would be typified by Herbert Hoover, a self-proclaimed individualist who nonetheless favored higher taxes on the rich, at least in 1920, who thought that Coolidge had not trust-busted enough yet would not have trust-busted as much as LaFollette, and who disliked government enterprises, let 14 Others who might belong here are George alone nationalization. Record, Irving Lenroot, Jonathan Bourne, William Randolph Hearst, and perhaps Louis Brandeis. The statist division of the center-left 27 would include the more leftist of the corporate liberals. Perhaps Theodore Roosevelt in 1912, with his big business support and plat- form containing "social justice" proposals, belongs here with most of his Progressive Party, and perhaps WOodrow Wilson should belong here after adopting many of their proposals in 1916 (if Gabriel Kolko's view of him as more inclined toward what we have called con- centration than toward what we have called competition is accurate). This category might be typified by William Allen White, with his "sympathy for the underdog" coupled with his "middle-class fears of the social revolution Roosevelt was guiding", as Otis Graham described his attitudes. Others who seem to belong here include Albert Beveridge, Gifford Pinchot, and Raymond Moley.15 The statist division of the right (the right corporate liberals) might be typified by Leonard Wood, an advocate of strong government with a pronounced anti-left inclination. Probably Woodrow Wilson belongs here between 1913 and 1916 (again assuming Kolko's view of his stand on the con- centration issue is accurate.) Others who seem to belong here include Bainbridge Colby, James Burleson, Atlee Pomerene, Charles Evans Hughes and Henry Stimson.16 The existence of this new category of left corporate liberals indicates that many big businessmen came to support other forms of seemingly anti-business government intervention besides that of regulation of business. Apparently these businessmen concluded that these measures hurt smaller competitors more than them, just as did regulation,and were therefore beneficial to them. Further examples of this will be seen later. 28 By this point, we have partially integrated Hofstadter's typology into the modified Weinstein and conventional schemes, inso- far as the right column of the modified weinstein model corresponds to Hofstadter's conservatives, and the moderate and extreme left columns together correspond to Hofstadter's progressives. This leaves the later (New Deal) liberals of Hofstadter. In his scheme, they are to the left of the extreme left of the Progressive Era, including the radical progressives (the LaFollette-Bryan group) (see Figure 19). However, the stands of this group in favor of radical trust—busting and some nationalization put them to the left Soc. Later Lib. Progressives Conserv. Conserv. (New Deal and (Hofstadter's) (Class Lib.) (Tradit.) Post-New Deal) l [I Radical Moderates I (Neo-Pop. etc.) LaFollette, Bryan, etc. Figure l9.--Further integration of the Hofstadter and Weinstein models: the rightism of the radical progressives. of the New Dealers and in an extreme left position even by today's standards (see Figure 20). On the other hand, this is not true of their stands on other issues, on which they do not seem distinguish- able from the more moderate of Hofstadter's progressives. This means that the radical progressives are in some ways to the left of the New Dealers and in some ways to the right of them. This may be shown as in Figure 21. fl A.|.|1k val PER P( 4 Soc Fig Cu} beil bot iSS Pub in Do: 29 Progress. Later Progress. Conserv. (Hofstadter) Liberals (Hofstadter) Radical (New Deal- Moderate Eras, etc.) Figure 20.—-The extreme leftism of the radical progressives. Conserv. (Tradit.) Conserv. (Class. Lib.) Social. Mod. Prog. and Post— New Deal) Figure 21.-—The rightism and leftism of the radical progressives. This complex situation makes discussion of the group diffi- cult, and it would be best if we could regard them henceforth as being either to the right or to the left of the New Dealers, but not both. Fortunately, it happens that the LaFollette-Bryan group has been generally unable (since about the time of WOrld War I) to keep issues of radical trust-busting and nationalization at the center of public debate (indeed, the members of this group seem to be quite rare Therefore, we may ignore the cleavage from this in recent decades). point on. This means, since the LaFollette-Bryan group seems to be 30 separated from the more moderate of Hofstadter's progressives only by these issues, that we can treat the former as indistinguishable from the latter. Since we will be ignoring the issues which make the LaFollette-Bryan group seem extremely leftist, we will now regard them as simply to the right of the New Dealers, in the same category as the more moderate Left-Progressives (see Figure 22). Later Progressive Progressive Conserv. Liberals (Hofstadter) (Hofstadter) (New Deal, etc.) Radical Moderate l \ f t Later Progressive Conserv. Liberals (Hofstadter) (New Deal, etc.) Figure 22.-—Simplification of Figure 21. We may now consider the New Deal. The so-called "First New Deal" (1933-35) consisted mainly of business regulatory measures-- the NRA being the most important--and various subsidies. It seemed to move the country toward statism but not toward the left (toward equality). The "Second New Deal" (1935-39) was apparently a move toward the left with the Social Security Act (including unemployment compensation and Aid to Dependent Children as well as old-age pen- sions), the National Labor Relations Act and wage-and-hour legisla- tion. Also, it should be noted that the rise in personal income 31 taxes (including a lower exemption), initiated by Hoover, was per- manently retained, with some egalitarian variations (split-rate corporate taxes, taxation of dividends as personal income) in the Second New Deal. We may examine the New Deal in greater detail by considering James T. Patterson's Congressional Conservatism and the New Deal and Ronald L. Feinman's Twilight of Progressivism.l7 These works pro- vide grounds for thinking that the New Deal should be divided not into two parts, but into three: 1933-35, 1935-57 and 1937-39. As the New Deal moved left in 1935-37 (with the Social Security Act, the NLRA and especially higher income taxes--especially those on corporations, and new utility regulation--especially holding company divestiture) and in 1937-39 (with renewed relief programs, the Fair Labor Standards Act, proposals for public housing, etc.), its base of support shrank, as we will elaborate below. In his book, Patterson describes three kinds of conservative Democratic opponents of the New Deal, which he commonly calls "irreconcilables","conservatives" and "moderates", respectively (he does not always use "conservatives" to refer to the middle group, but we shall use the three terms in this way for convenience.) The first group was in opposition in all three periods, the second in the last two, and the third in the last period only. (In opposition to all of these were the steadfast supporters of Roosevelt and his New Deal, who stayed with him through all three periods and beyond. Those who remained New Dealers after 1937 generally had undisputed 32 hold on the title, and on that of "liberal"--in the modern sense-- as well.) As has been said, it seems that the New Deal, in 1933-35, moved mainly toward statism and not toward equality, while in 1935- 37 and 1937—39, it made two steps toward equality. This suggests that the moves of 1933-35 correspond to the boundary between Conser- vatives (classical liberals) and Right-Progressive Statists (Right- Corporate Liberals) in the model, while the moves of 1935-37 cor- respond to the boundary between Right-Progressive Statists and Left- Progressive Statists (Left-Corporate Liberals) and the moves of 1937-39 correspond to the boundary between the Left-Progressive Statists and the New Deal Liberals. If, as seems very likely, these correspondences are genuine, then Patterson's groups correspond to categories from the model as follows: irreconcilable Democrats to Conservatives (Classical Liberals), conservative Democrats to Right- Progressive Statists, moderate Democrats to Left-Progressive Statists, and liberal New Deal Democrats, of course, to New Deal Liberals (see Figure 23). Turning now to Feinman, we can see that his "Progressive Republicans" seem to be political heirs of the "insurgent" Republi- cans of the Taft and Wilson administrations, and to have been men ‘who would fit in the Left-Progressive category, constituting their left wing--or their entire membership (the matter is unclear): indeed, Borah, Hiram Johnson and LaFollette's son are included in the group. In any case, this category includes the leftwardmost of 33 LaFollette, etc . Cons. Hoover (Class Lib.) "Progressive "Cons. Repu ." Republicans" "Irreconcilable (Feinman) Democrats" New Deal Progressive Progressive Libs. Statists Statists (L) (R) "New Deal "Mod. Dems." "Cons. Dems." Libs. Dems." Figure 23.--The New Deal Era: integration of the Patterson and Feinman categories into model. 34 those who would have fallen in Hofstadter's progressive category. These progressive Republicans, Feinman seems to indicate, thought that Franklin Roosevelt was generally too far to the right in the 1933-35 period, about where he ought to be in the 1935-37 period, and too far to the left in the third. It also appears that they feared his statism from the first, as they worried over concentration of power, wasteful spending and partisan use of relief programs. It seems that this group would fall in the left-progressive column of the model, along with the moderate Democrats of Patterson, insofar as both groups supported the leftward moves of Roosevelt in 1935-37, while opposing his leftward moves of 1937-39. It would also seem that these progressive Republicans were on the anti-statist side (although perhaps not as much so as most conservative Republi- cans and irreconcilable Democrats). These conclusions based on the Patterson and Feinman books are represented in Figure 23. Now let us look at the Republican party, as it emerged at the end of this period and remained in the ensuing decades. Its members are commonly grouped into two wings: the "conservative" wing (known as the "Old Guard", etc.) and the "liberal", "moderate" or "moderate-to-liberal" wing (known as "Modern Republicans", etc.). On economic policy, the main difference is supposedly over whether they, in general, approved or disapproved of the New Deal. RObert Taft was the leader of the former; Dewey and Willkie of the latter. The latter group does seem to have accepted much of the New Deal,17 especially the social insurance measures of the Second New Deal. 35 There appears to be an association between the moderate-to- liberal wing and big ("Wall Street") business. There is reason to believe that many of the apparently egalitarian measures of the New Deal were, as many of those of the Progressive Era were, examples of corporate liberalism. It appears that many big businessmen came to support much of the New Deal. They discovered that New Deal social welfare and labor legislation could benefit them. In fact, support for Theodore Roosevelt in 1912, who was advocating precursors of many of these programs that year, came from a significant number of big businessmen. Such businessmen seem to have concluded that the taxes which pay for social welfare programs and the burdens of dealing with strong unions would hurt their smaller competitors more than them--as seemed to be the case with Progressive Era regulatory measures. This association of big business with this wing of the party is matched by an association of small ("Main Street") business with its conservative wing. This suggests the NAM conservatives of the Progressive Era,18 just as the Dewey-Eisenhower group suggests the old corporate liberals of the NCF. The big difference between these scenarios is the interven- tion of the New Deal, and the acceptance by the Dewey-Eisenhower group of it, or at least of its basics, which means that this group is on the left of the corporate liberal category--right or left wings. 36 Or does it? Perhaps social insurance and wage-and-hour laws are not as egalitarian as they seem. Social insurance, if paid for entirely by the recipient, is not redistributionist, and if it merely redistributes from the young to the old, it need not redistribute from one class to another. Even such egalitarianism as does exist may not be more pronounced than what existed under nineteenth-century welfare arrangements. And the contributions of the employer may burden him as does the corporate income tax; insofar as they hurt small business more than large business, both measures can be regarded as inegalitarian. Wage-and-hour laws may work in a similar manner, and maximum-hours laws in particular may be seen as paternalistic rather than redistributionist. And while the National Labor Rela- tions Act (NLRA) (the "Wagner Act") was surely, overall, a major departure from laissez-faire in a pro-union direction (particularly in its provisions relating to union elections, union recognition and "unfair" practices of management), its provisions which simply legalized unions was not a departure from laissez-faire (unless, of course, one regarded unions as inclined toward being monopolistic interferences with the free market.) As it happens, the social security act, the NLRA, and the NRA, which includes minimum-wage provisions, received considerable support even from those who were commonly called conservatives (most of whom opposed other major New Deal legislation of 1935 and after). Most old progressives, according to Graham, had little objection to these. Furthermore, Al Smith was a long-time advocate of minimum-wage 37 laws, while he and other Liberty Leaguers approved of the principle of Social Security. Thus, the "New Dealism" of the Dewey-Eisenhower group, or some of them, need not have put them to the left of the moderate left or even of the right, on Figure 18. However, their apparent toleration for the expansion of government involved in the Hoover tax increase and the overall spending increase of the New Deal (which were not reversed in succeeding decades) meant that this group may have been at least as far left as the Progressive left statists (left corporate liberals). All of this being true about many of the "Moderate-to-liberal" Republicans does not exhaust the possibilities of greater egalitar- ianism in members of the group. As Gary Reichard points out in his Republicanism Reaffirmed, Eisenhower was not very closely associated with the more explicitly liberal members of his party such as Javits, and was not really a liberal Republican in the same sense that they were. Dewey may not have been either, Reichard is inclined to believe.19 This does not, however, prevent other Republicans from being liberal in the New Deal sense. Thus, we now have Republicans as well as Democrats in the New Deal liberal category. ‘This category would be for people who accepted those policies of the New Deal (and later) which repre- sented a move to the left of left-wing Progressivism. These might include pro-union stands on collective-bargaining issues and on minimum-wage increases, and skewing of social insurance 38 benefit-contribution ratios and income tax rates in a more egali- tarian direction. It nonetheless seems likely that most New Deal "liberal" Republicans were somewhere to the right of most New Deal Democrats, perhaps on such things as deficit spending, which is commonly seen as uniting both wings of the Republican party against the Democrats. 50, in regard to the New Deal, we may end up with left-wing and right-wing New Deal categories (see Figure 24). ZQFbI Cons. Jette‘ Hoover New Deal Progressive Statists (Left) (Right) Humphrey Javits (L) (R) Figure 24,-Rightist (Republican) New Dealers. Since leaving the discussion of the Progressive Era, the course of our investigation has allowed us to say relatively little of the liberty dimension. In this regard, the Dewey-Eisenhower group and the New Deal liberals, right and left, all seem to fall mainly on the relatively statist side of the chart. Occasionally, a left- leaning politician with somewhat pepulistic tendencies seems to object to statism, and so follow in the footsteps of Hoover, Bryan and LaFollette, but to their left, on New Deal and post-New Deal issues (see Figure 25). 39 £656 Cons 12st (Class. Lib.) {e . McGovern? Hatfield? Hoover Progressive Statists Humphrey? Javits? (L) (R) Figure 25.--The Anti-Statist row extended leftward. There is some reason for thinking that more than two levels are needed in the liberty dimension. For all of their inclination toward regulated concentration rather than competition in the area of business that characterizes the Dewey-Eisenhower group and Woodrow Wilson, and for all the acceptance of social insurance of at least the former, both seem to have a real abhorrence of big government. The "Modern Republicanism" of the Eisenhower adminis- tration, as it is interpreted by Arthur Larson, has a presumption against government,20 as do the attitudes of Wilson, even after he moved toward accepting the "New Nationalism" of Theodore Roosevelt.21 This seems in contrast to Theodore Roosevelt (although the contrast may be mainly rhetorical), who claimed that Jeffersonian mistrust of government was out-of-date. This also seems to be in contrast to most New Deal liberalism. Thus, we might distinguish three, 40 instead of two, levels on the liberty dimension--libertarian, moder- ate and statist (see Figure 26). ‘\\‘\\ Cons. Hoover Dewey Al Smith Eisenhower Wilson Wilson (1913-1916) (1916-? Hamilton T. Roosevelt J. Connally Figure 26.--Degrees of Statism. The next step in the evolution of the model leads us to move ahead to modern times, and to a discussion of the ideological changes that occurred in the 19605 and 19705. Ideological classifi- cations proposed regarding this era deal with the expansion of the inventory of liberal programs beyond the New Deal levels. The Great Society of Lyndon Johnson led to disaffection from the Democratic party by many voters and political figures who had supported the liberalism of the Democrats during the New Deal, and Fair Deal and New Frontier years. 41 Kevin Phillips, in his book, The Emegging Republican Majority, clarified the differences between the older kind of liberal, who was leaving the party in the 19605, and the newer kind, who welcomed the change.22 (Others, such as Walter Dean Bean Burnham, Everett Carl Ladd, Jr., Jeffrey Hart and William A. Rusher have drawn similar pictures.)23 The former kind of liberal was oriented toward the working class and lower-middle class; the latter kind was oriented toward the very poor, especially the hard-core unemployed and the inner-city-dwellers. The former was "populistic"--suspicious of elites, whether they were economic, intellectual or political; the latter was led by an intellectual, political and economic elite. The former thus represented the lower-middle and lower classes; the latter united the very poor with rich and upper-middle class intellectuals, bureaucrats and businessman who created, ran and/or profited by the programs (the last being the latest variation on the corporate liberal theme, it would seem). The former was seen as practicing taxation of the few (rich) to help the many (working poor), while the latter was seen as practicing taxation of the many (middle and lower-middle classes, who were pushed into higher tax brackets, and who suffered from the tax of inflation) to help the few poor (slum dwellers). Such was the pic- ture drawn by Phillips and others--most of whom were more sympathetic to the former kind of liberalism, and saw themselves as spokesmen for the interest groups that it represented--and such is the way this group generally seemed to feel about the effects of the newer social programs, whatever the facts may have been.24 42 (Many of the so-called "neo-conservatives", with their implicit or avowed liking for the welfare state or the New Deal but not the Great Society, seem to fit the image of the first type of liberal.) Phillips' book, moreover, implies a two-dimensionality to the differences among modern liberals. As the unfolding of the Great Society agenda repelled many hitherto strong supporters of the New Deal and post-New Deal welfare state (mostly Democrats), it was attracting other people (mostly Republicans) who had been more or less unsupportive of earlier programs, but who were now coming around to support them. Thus, Great Society and pre-Great Society liberalism may be more than just degrees on a scale of post-New Deal liberalism; they may represent two separate dimensions of modern liberalism--that is, of what we have called herein "New Deal liberalism (left and right)". This would allow the creation of four sub-categories of this liberalism; those who were conservative (classical liberal) on both dimensions; those who were liberal (modern liberal) on both; those who were conservative on the Great Society but liberal on previous programs; and those who were conser- vative on previous post-New Deal programs but liberal on the Great Society. It would appear that the first and last categories are subdivisions of the New Deal right category of previous charts, and that the second and third are subdivisions of the New Deal left category, each of the older categories being bisected by the division over the new Great Society program, as in Figure 27.25 43 [Size of boxes has no significance] Cons. Hoover .N ew Deal~ P i S i (left) so rogress ve tat sts R. (R1 L R 83’2“ gbt) ( ) ( ) 0118 Figure 27.--The New Deal versus Great Society liberalism. 44 ENDNOTES 1Robert S. Erikson and Norman R. Luttbeg, American Public Opinion: Its Origins, Content and Impact (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1973). (P. 63 refers to both attitudes toward e uality and toward government.) Clinton Rossiter, Parties and Poli- tics in America (Ithaca; Cornell University Press, 1960), esp. pp. 135-6, (where attitudes toward big government are referred to, with much reference to implicit class connection, showing the ambiguity of the definition) and pp. 127, 139, 179. 2On the change from classical to modern liberalism, see Angus Campbell, Philip E. Converse, Warren E. Miller and Donald E. Stokes (The American Voter (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1960), pp. 193-4. On the modern identification of classical liberal- ism and conservatism, see Friedrich A. Hayek, "Why I Am Not a Con- servative" in The Constitution of Liberty (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1960), pp. 397-411, esp. p. 397-8; Russell Kirk, "Conservatism" in the Encyclopgdia Britannica, vol. 6, pp. 371-4 (Chicago: Encyclopedia Britannica, Inc” 1966)- esp. Po 371; Peter Viereck, Conservatism Revisited (New York: Macmillan, 1962), p. 131; Clinton Rossiter, Conservatism in America: The Thankless Persuasion (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1955). 3 Hayek, "Why I Am Not a Conservative", pp. 98-99. 4See Louis Hartz, The Liberal Tradition in America: An Interpretation of American Political Thogght Since the Revolution (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, 1955). 5Some such as Hartz and others of the "consensus school" see a (classical and modern) liberal consensus dominating the history of the U.S., including the South, although they recognize some tradi- tionalist elements there. It should be noted that the South could be liberal relative to European traditionalists and still be tradi- tionalist relative to the rest of the country. In any case, further examination of these issues will have to wait until the voting records are examined. Whether the South is traditionalist or liberal, the question remains whether it is overwhelmingly conservative (traditionalist or classical liberal) or whether liberals (modern liberals) and conser- vatives were more evenly matched. Among those close to the latter position is Dewey W. Grantham, Jr., who, in his The Democratic South (Athens, GA: University of Georgia Press, 1963), pp. 44-52, talks 45 of the "populism" and "radicalism" of men such as James Vardaman. Among those closer to the former position is J. Morgan Kousser, in his The Shaping_of Southern Politics: Suffrage Restriction and the Establishment of the One-Party South, 1880-1910 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1974). He points out the conservative alliances and policies of Vardaman and others were prominent after disfranchise- ment of the lower classes (PP. 231-7). It seems that much of the liberalism, at least at the low points of voter turnout (c. 1908-48, as shown in Southern Politics and the Second Reconstruction, by Nunan V. Bartley and Hugh D. Graham; Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 1975; pp. 8-10) was only apparent: some was rhetorical only, and other aspects involved business regulation (whose inegali- tarian possibilities have already been discussed) and regionalism (aid to agriculture, rural development, public transportation systems, and the kind of business regulation and tax policies which favor state businesses over national, out-of-state businesses). Further explanation will occur upon consideration of voting records. 6The view of the Progressive Era generally held by historians of the so-called "progressive" school such as Charles Beard and Arthur Schlesinger, Jr. 7Richard Hofstadter, The Age of Reform: From Bryan to F.D.R. (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1955). 8Ibid. Also, Otis L. Graham, Jr. in Encore for Reform (New York: Oxford University Press, 1967) implies a similar distinction, among those Progressives who opposed the New Deal, he points out an aversion to class politics, interest group politics and unbalanced budgets as being typical of them, especially on pp. 24-100. 9James Weinstein, The Corporate Ideal in the Liberal State, 1200-1918, (Boston: Beacon Press, 1968). Also Gabriel Kolko, in The Triumph of Conservatism: A Reinterpretation of American History 1900-1916, (New York: Macmillan, 1963), has had many influential things to say about the matter. 10Weinstein, especially pp. 4-6. 11David P. Thelen, Robert M. LaFollette and the Insurgent Spirit, (Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1976), pp. 10-13. 12LaFollette and most of the insurgents supported the FTC (James Holt, Congressional Insurgents and the Party System 1909-1916 [Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1967]), and supported the principle of a federal reserve system (PP. 107—11). Bryan was not generally known for objecting to the domestic measures of the Wilson administration during his years in it. 46 13Jean Hoff Wilson, Herbert Hoover: Forgotten Progressive (Boston: Little, Brown, and Co., 1975). Other assignments to this category are made on the basis of reading Graham and others. Record, Lenroot and Bourne are placed here on the basis of reading Otis Graham's Encore for Reform. Hearst is placed here because of his quasi-populist reputation. Louis Brandeis is placed here because of his reputation as a progressive supporter of competition with a sympathy for small business interests. 14Graham, Encore for Refomg, and others. Beveridge is placed here because he is sometimes counted among the "insurgent" opponents of President Taft while being nonetheless an admirer of John Marshall. The others are placed here on the basis of reading Graham's Encore for Reform. 15Colby, Burleson and Pomerene are placed here on the basis of Graham's Encore for Reform. Hughes and Stimson are placed here because of their reputations as progressives (as governor of New York and member of the cabinet, respectively) who came to support Taft in 1912. 16Ronald L. Feinman, Twilight of Prggressivism: The Western Republican Senators and the New Deal (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1980) and James T. Patterson, Congressional Conser- vatives and the New Deal: the Growth of the Conservative Coalition in Congress, 1933-39 (Lexington, University of Kentucky Press, 1967). 17The NAM was no longer so much a small-business organiza- tion as it was in the earlier time, whether because power had shifted to the larger members or because the average member had grown. How- ever, in any case, the small versus large distinction may have to be modified for the earlier period as well. Rather than there being a positive correlation between size and liberalism, there may have actually been a negative one for most businesses, with the smallest businessmen tending to be Hofstadter-type or LaFollette type progres- sives, and moderately large manufacturers being more to the right. Probably it is only beyond a certain high threshold of size that liberalism is strong. And this liberalism may not even be a func- tion of size as such--it may have to do with central geographic loca- tion or other factors. All that is important for this paper is (1) that there are major ideological cleavages in the business community, and (2) there is not a simple negative correlation between liberalism and size. 18Gary Reichard, The Reaffirmation of Republicanism: Eisen- hower and the Eighty—ThirdICongress (Rfioxville: ‘The University Press, 1978). 19Arthur Larson, What We Are For (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1959). 47 20Arthur S. Link, Woodrow Wilson and the Progressive Era, 1910-1917 (New York: Harper & Row, 1954), pp. 223-30. 21Kevin P. Phillips, The Emerging Republican Majority (Garden City, NY: Doubleday, 1969). 22Walter Dean Burnham, Critical Elections and the Mainsprings of American Politics (New York: W. W. Norton, 1970);William A. Rusher, The Making of the New Majority Party (Ottawa, 111.: Green Hill Publishers, 1975) Everett Carl Ladd Jr., with Charles D. Hadley, Transformations of the American Party System: Political Coalitions from the New Deal to the 1970;§_(New York: W. W. Norton, 1975). 23Sar A. Levitan and Robert Taggart, in The Promise Of Great- ness (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1976), argue that the national income share of the upper two quintiles decreased as that of the lower one increased in the 1963-68 period (PP. 250-1). This was partially because of the growth of social security and related programs, which outweighed the growth in welfare and the New Great Society programs. Interestingly, the former programs are not the ones of that era which are most talked about by conservatives or liberals. The latter ones were, even though they were smaller--and it is the redistribution that they caused that the people described by Phillips had most in mind. 24Other ideological classifications of interest have been made by Clinton Rossiter in Conservatism in America: The Thankless Persuasion (New York: Alford A. Knopf, 1958) and by a James ReichleyiJIConservatism in an Age of Change: The Nixon and Ford légministrations (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institute, 1981). CHAPTER II METHODOLOGY Now that we have presented the classification which consti— tutes the theoretical model, we may begin to take steps to enable us to test it. We shall therefore discuss the methodology that we will be using. The methodological topic to be considered first is that of the scope of the investigation to be undertaken. Were it possible, it would be desirable to make a universally comprehensive ideological classification which would cover political attitudes throughout history. Such a grand project is beyond the scope of this paper; therefore, many reductions in scope have had to be made. In making the decisions necessary to do so, the attempt has been made to find the range of subject which comes closest to achieving the two frequently incompatible ends: wide applicability and manage- able size. This attempt was apparent in the choice of the arena to be studied. National politics was selected as the location of the study because it exhibits more diversity than the politics of any one state while the fact that it is a single political arena makes the study more manageable than a study of several states. The study of roll-call voting records on a national level means a study of those of Congress. It was necessary to select one chamber of Congress to examine, as to examine both would make the 48 49 scope of the study too large. So the Senate was chosen over the House of Representatives because of the more manageable size. A similar balance was sought in the determination of the time frame of the study. The criterion of manageability favors the selection of a short period; that of representativeness favors the selection of a long one. This is the same principle which provides that in taking a sample from a population, the best sample, all else being equal, is the one which is most representative of the varia- tion of the population--which means that it must represent as much of the variety of the population as possible. Therefore, the best "sample" time period would be the one which covers the most histori- cal change (relevant to the study) within it. That would mean the time frame that stretched across the most historical time boundaries. The maximum amount of time over which it would be feasible to study voting records, for this sort of work, seems to be about twenty years. Therefore, the attempt was made to find a twenty-year slice of time which encompassed the most possible change (in matters of interest to this study). Some limitations on where the search for this time frame was to be conducted were already set. Since records are generally better in more recent years, and since Congressional Quarterly, which was chosen as the data base for the paper (see below), publishes roll-call voting records only as far back as 1945, it was decided that the time frame selected would have to be post-1944. On the other hand, since the events of the Reagan administration are 50 perhaps too recent for proper historical perspective, 1980 seems to be the last year that could be examined. Within this general period, there is much to suggest that, in United States politics, the biggest changes occurred, in a more— or-less related manner, in the late 1960s and early 19705, and that this period, or the start of it, constitutes a major historical dividing line, and the end of it may constitute another. This period was characterized not only by the arrival and perpetuation of the Great Society programs, by political turmoil and by a rela- tively high degree of liberalism compared to earlier and later periods, but also by the presence of issues and cleavages that were distinctive. Some of the Great Society programs and especially spending increases provided new issues insofar as they were, in earlier times, so unlikely to be enacted into law as not to be a major issue at the center of political concern. Not commonly noticed among these was the biggest of them all, the increase in the Social Security program, especially in 1967, 1969 and 1972. More- over, welfare (AFDC) spending became a major issue at this time. And then there were the "social issues" and Vietnam. These were mostly new issues. Similarly, the cleavages of the time were dis- tinctive. Not only were the Northern and Southern Democrats divided from each other, but the Northern Democrats and Republicans were divided internally, with alliances frequently reaching across the borders of the groups. The end point of this turbulent and liberal period is regarded here as being after the 1974 elections (in November 1974 or 51 January l975)--after the end of the Vietnam War, the departure of Nixon and especially the fading of the New Left and the Counter- culture, plus the election of a heavily Democratic Congress that nonetheless was, in some ways, not as economically liberal as its predecessors. In the ensuing years, some of the issues of the pre- ceding period (especially poverty, welfare and the non-economic issues) were de-emphasized, in favor of older concerns such as unemployment, inflation and taxes. Similarly, some of the cleavages of the 1965-74 period faded as some older patterns of cleavage began to re-emerge (e.g. the 1976 Presidential election tended to align the East and South behind the Democrats and the Midwest and West behind the Republicans, in much the same way as the 1960 election did). Since, as has been stated, we wish our time frame to encom- pass change and stretch across historical period boundaries, it should cover the above-discussed turbulent and liberal period (circa 1965-74), and stretch backward and forward in time to encompass parts of the preceding and succeeding periods. Thus, we would be able to sample political history in three of the major subperiods (1945-65, 1965-75, 1975-80) of the 1945-80 period in American his- tory. The length of two Congresses (four years) seems like a reason- able minimum length of time on each side of the base period for com- parison. This would make the time frame run from the start of the 87th Congress (1961) to the close of the 95th (1978). However, in the case of the preceding period, the time frame was extended 52 further back to 1959 because the elections of 1958 were an important turning point insofar as they brought a Democratic landslide and, more importantly, they are a convenient place to begin from the point of view of bookkeeping, as so many political careers began in 1958 and so many ended then. The time frame is thus 1959 to 1978. This time frame also has the advantage of allowing the comparison of two periods of Republican control of the White House with two of Democratic control. In regard to the issues to be examined, the need to keep the scope from being too wide dictated the selection of only one major issue area to study. The desire for a broad range favored the choice of the category of economic issues, and so this area was chosen. The category of economic issues is larger, both in number of issues and in number of votes, than any other major category of issues: foreign affairs, racial issues, crime-related issues, etc.--even the large category of "social issues" (which includes the last two categories, among others). Economic issues provide the bulk of the subjects of day-to-day political struggle. In addition, economic issues have several other claims to priority. Ideologies often derive their stands on other issues from their economic principles. This is largely because most other political issues have an economic aspect, if only in regard to the issues of who will pay the cost of a given government activity (e.g. administration of a civil-rights regulation or increasing our nuclear weapons arsenal) and how peeple will be financially effected by it 53 (e.g. how the civil rights bill will affect the trade of the merchant to whom it is applied, or who gets the contract to build the weapon). Indeed, almost anything which involves material things (including the human body and its labor power) has an economic aspect. And those things which do not have an economic aspect (e.g. spiritual matters) are really beyond government power to control anyway. 80 almost anything which can concern politics has an economic aspect. Furthermore, some ideologies (e.g. capitalism, socialism, communism) even advertise how important they consider economic issues by taking their names from the economic system they advocate. "Economic issues" will be taken to mean those which have as their main concern the government's management of material wealth, including its role in the distribution of it. As we have noted, many issues, including all of those involving spending, have econo- mic aspects, but not all are primarily concerned with these aspects, and those which are not we will exclude. For example, the cost of buying new weapons for our nuclear arsenal and the cost of prosecut- ing criminals are issues, but they are not generally considered to be the most important aspects of the debates over the issue areas of nuclear arms and law enforcement. Therefore, these two issue areas and others like them, are not commonly considered economic issues, and votes on these subjects will therefore be excluded from consideration. The determination of exactly which votes involve economic issues entails some difficulty. As Lee Anderson, Meredith Watts and 54 Allen Wilcox point out in their Legislative Roll-Call Analysis,1 the votes in question may not really be about the subjects they appear to be about. For example, an anti-busing amendment to an education appropriations bill would seem to be a racial ("civil- rights") issue rather than an education spending issue. Yet some may try to attach the amendment to cause the bill to lose some of its supporters, and supporters of the amendment may vote against it in response to this strategy. This would seem to create a problem. Nonetheless, we need not consider it a great obstacle. Few would deny that there is a strong correlation between the apparent and the real subjects of bills, and that the great majority of the time they are the same. Moreover, when one has several votes on the same (apparent) issue area, over several years, as this study does in a number of cases, and if one then sees that most or all of these votes exhibit similar cleavages, it is unlikely that all or most of the votes are other than what they seem. This points to the advan- tage of scaling votes,which is similar to what is being done here (in the theoretical classification and later in the results of the examination of the votes), and scaling is recommended by Anderson, Watts and Wilcox (as well as others) as just such a way of reducing the problems of selecting votes (see below). The demands of manageability set further limits on the issue range. Votes involving only one area of industry, such as agricul- ture, mining, natural resources, or energy, will be excluded, barring some other reasons for including them (as in the case of gas 55 rationing votes, which are included because they are among the rela- tively few votes dealing with the regulation of business). There is room in this paper for consideration of only issues of general interest. The data base of this paper will consist of a compilation of votes from.which the list of votes to be examined will be drawn. This data base of votes will consist of those compiled by Congres- sional Quarterly (QQ). The use of 9Q in this way is a common prac— tice. We made this decision for two reasons. The first, is that E9 provides a digest of the votes in the Congressional Record, leav- ing out the most routine votes. The second reason is that QQDpro- vides a tabulation of votes--and not only actual votes and announced pairs (derivable from the Congressional Record), but also of announced stands and answers to surveys conducted by ER itself. All of these will be counted as votes in this paper, as we desire that as much evidence as possible on the stands taken by Senators on the issues be obtained; survey responses, announcements and even pairs may not indicate as much commitment as actual votes, but they should indicate which way a Senator is leaning, which is enough for our purposes. The particular §Q_compilation that will be used as the primary data base is drawn from the lists found in gg's annual Almanaog. The number of votes in these lists normally ranged from over 300 to over 500 for each year in the years in question. The total number of votes per year is too large for this study. It might be a reasonable figure for a study with a time 56 frame of two or four years,2 but for one with a time frame of twenty years such as this one, a reduction in the number of votes needs to be made. The problem lies in how we are to do it. Various authors have warned of the problems involved in selecting votes using impres- sionistic evaluations of the subject matter.3 As William Riker points out, such criteria may be subjective (or at least not objec- tively provable) and so not reproducible by other investigators. In spite of such criticisms, there are authors who do indulge in this practice. Michael Foley, who did a study with a fourteen- year time frame, included only votes that he thought involved "major policy" issues, and which involved the liberal-conservative conflict that he was interested in; in his study of the Eighty-Third Congress Gary Reichard examined votes in several predetermined categories in a way similar to Foley's. However, both of these then screened out those votes which did not scale.4 "Scaling" of issues is a way of arranging them in a definite order, such that those who vote one way ("yes", for example) on a given issue will vote that way (yes) on all succeeding issues in the scale, while at the same time those who vote the opposite way (in this case, "no") will vote in that way (no) on all the preceding issues of the scale. In a perfect scale, then, there is no overlap in the cleavages created by the issues on that scale. This suggests that all of the issues are indicators of a common underlying vari- able, in that they merely represent different degrees of attitudes 57 on the same dimension. And if one assigns numbers to the various positions on a scale, then each of those numbers will describe a specific combination of stands on all of the votes or the issues on the scale (in contrast to what is true of an "index", wherein describing a person as having a score of 78% "conservative", for example, on a given set of votes, gives one no indication as to which 78% of the votes it is on which the person is conservative). A large set of issues which scale perfectly is seldom found, so a certain percentage of perfect scalability (usually 90%) is more or less arbitrarily regarded as acceptable for constituting a scale. Anderson, Watts and Wilcox propose scaling as a way of getting around this problem;5 and many other authors join them in praise of scaling.6 Such a method does have many advantages, as it is reproducible and allows the voting legislators to "speak for themselves" (as Riker put it) about which votes are important (i.e., those cleavages which are similar over many votes, or at least parallel [scalable], suggesting a common underlying issue; such an issue, which manifests itself in a large number of votes, may for that reason alone can be regarded as important to those voting). However, while scaling will screen out some votes and so reduce the number of votes, the researcher will still have to con- sider and compare all of the votes in whatever pool of votes with which he starts, even though he will eventually eliminate some by using the scale. This is fine if the original pool is not too large 58 for one's purposes. However, if it is too large, as ours is, one will still need to find a way to reduce the number of votes, before or in place of scaling. Such a screening of votes is a topic less often treated than is that of scaling. NOnetheless, we may consider it as best we can; we may use the two main categories used by Anderson, Watts and Wilcox to guide the discussion. One consists of those methods which do not take into account the substance of the bill; the other consists of those which do.7 The former category includes such mechanistic methods as selecting only votes with a certain amount of dissent and using random selection. The first of the two methods in this category uses only those votes in which the size of the minority side was greater than a given percentage of the total vote, on the assumption that the least closely contested votes are the least important.8 This is a bad procedure, at least for this study, for it works contrary to our purposes. Making the categories used in this thesis is much like the constructing of a scale. As one approaches the end of a scale, the sides of each cleavage necessarily became more and more unequal, one growing larger and the other growing smaller. Similarly, in this thesis, we have very large and very small cate- gories, and are interested in all of them. In both cases, all categories are important and of interest. Therefore, there is no warrant for a procedure which ignores votes which are won by large majorities. (There may be ground for ignoring small groups because 59 they are too small in absolute size for one to be sure they are not idiosyncratic and random, but this is a different issue.) The second proposed method in the first category, suggested by Anderson, Watts and Wilcox, is that of choosing votes by random selection.9 However, using such a procedure--and using the previous procedure as we11--means abandoning the attempt to sort out the important votes on the merits of their subject matter. It would be better, then, to use some other method which did take account of the subject if some way could be found of avoiding the weaknesses of the impressionistic procedures mentioned above. The second category consists of methods of selecting votes which do consider their subject matter. The dangers of subjectivity in selecting votes this way have already been noted.10 However, since this is merely a preliminary selection of votes to examine (to see if there is any evidence for the existence today of the theoretical categories), rather than a selection of votes to be used to determine how a classification is to be devised or an index is to be constructed, and since we are not trying to weight votes (beyond saying whether they are or are not worth studying), we will not attempt to achieve more rigorous standards. Devising criteria for selecting votes that can secure general acceptance would seem to require extensive study of the votes. The complexity of legislative maneuvering often makes it necessary to follow the legislative process very closely in order to decide which votes are important and meaningful and which are not. Not only must 60 the bills and amendments be selected, but it must be determined which vote on each of them is important. The votes on "tabling" (killing) a bill, passing it, passing a conference version of it, and over- riding a veto may all be different from each other; the votes on passing, tabling, reconsidering or tabling the reconsideration of an amendment may also vary. Which votes are important and which repre- sent the "real" stands of Senators on an issue must be determined. It would seem that nothing short of an in-depth study of the legis- lative history of the bills in question could give solid answers to these questions. It might therefore be necessary to rely on some "expert" individuals or organizations who might evaluate the data for us. If such an expert was generally recognized as such, then we would have general agreement on the soundness of the list of selected votes. We might be able to minimize such danger of biased judgement that still remains by getting a panel of such experts (individuals or organizations) to screen the votes, and then following the con- sensus. (Riker objects to using such panels of experts. They may not, he maintains, use the same standard for evaluating votes, and therefore their collective decisions would not be meaningful.11 This argument does not seem sound. The logic of scaling, of which Riker seems to approve, says that similar or at least parallel cleavages of votes--which votes thus scale--indicate a common under- lying issue which the scale brings out. The logic of using a panel of experts is similar. If they produce similar lists of votes, 61 then this is strong reason for believing that they are using similar standards to evaluate the importance of the votes.) Who are the "experts" on whom we should rely? We should choose from those who closely observe the legislative body in ques- tion, either from the inside or from the outside. An example of the former procedure was a study by Wilder Crane which used six members of the legislature that he was studying to help him select votes. Using such personal consultation is not within the plan of this thesis, and gives rise to other problems, such as those of deciding which legislators to choose. It would seem better to consult out- side organizations which make it their business to watch the legis- lative body, and which publish reports on their findings.12 In the case of Congress, there are several such bodies. Since there still may be too much bias involved in picking one, as Foley noted, it would seem best to adhere to the "panel" principle and choose more than one organization. We may then make a list of votes out of those mentioned by all of the panel groups, or by a certain number of the groups. If we pick a number and then continue to add to the panel, we will tend to increase the number of votes on the final list; if we increase the number of panelists on whose lists the vote must appear to be included on ours, while keeping the number of groups on the panel constant, then we will reduce the number of votes on our list. It was eventually decided to use three panelists and require that at least two mention a vote. TWO would be the lowest number to provide corroboration for a vote choice, 62 and so would require corroboration without making the requirements for inclusion too strict. The following lists, compiled by such organizations, were eventually selected: the conservative Americans for Constitutional Action (ACA)'s ACA Index (from 1963 through 1978), the AFL-CIO's Committee on Political Education (COPE)'s Labor Looks at Congress (from 1959 through 1978) and ng5 annual list of "Key Votes" (pub- lished annually in Qg's Almanac and every four years in its Congress and the Nation);3 The list of votes which were merely touched on in COPE's publication would be very long, even if all votes outside the chosen subject areas were eliminated. A list of only those relevant votes where the number of votes on each side was reported would also be very long. Therefore, it was decided to use the list that could be made of only those votes which COPE judged important enough to put, along with the numbers, in boldface type, and which were in the relevant subject areas. This particular combination of organizations has much to commend them. Congressional Quarterly is in the full-time business of watching and interpreting Congress. It seems that their selec- tions, especially those of which votes on each bill are important, deserve considerable attention. And, as has been said, 29 is often used as a data base in roll-call analysis. The other two organizations, ACA and COPE, are both political pressure groups. Their voting records are compiled mainly for pur- poses of rating legislators as friendly or unfriendly to their 63 causes, and so are somewhat of a sideline. This is in contrast to the case of 9g, and makes their judgement in this somewhat less valuable. On the other hand, the fact that both of these are pressure groups gives them a keen interest in the business before Congress. Since one of the components of the "importance" of a vote is the degree to which people believe it to be important, the testimony of these actors in the political arena is particularly valuable in this matter. The two balance each other well, the ACA being a conservative group and the AFL-CIO being a liberal group; also, the former is an ideological group, while the latter is an economic interest group. Since 9Q is officially neither conservative nor liberal and is neither an ideological pressure group nor an interest group, this inclusion on the panel does not upset these balances. In addition, for shorter periods of time, we will make use of the United States Chamber of Commerce's political newsletter, Congressional Action (hereinafter £9) (for the year 1978), and The Almanac of American Politics (hereinafter éég) (1972 through 1980), by Michael Barone, Grant Ujifusa, and Douglas Mathews (for the years 1973 through 1978).14 Back issues of the Chamber's newsletter are almost unavailable, the 1978 issue being the only one available in our time frame; the 5193232 only began publishing in 1972. Nonethe— less, both provide some interesting votes. (One other rating organization, the liberal Americans for Democratic Action [ADA], was also considered. Its newsletter was 64 initially rejected because some years were not available, but, as we have just seen, two other organizations with lists that did not cover the time frame were used. This organization was finally rejected because it provided few new kinds of votes, and because the AFL-CIO is a liberal ideological organization in all but name, as well as being a labor organization. The same cannot quite be said for the Chamber of Commerce as a conservative organization, and so it and the ACA provide more of a divergence of perspective than do the AFL-CIO and ADA, at least on economic issues.) All votes which appear on the lists of two of these five organizations will go onto the final list, to be used in this study. This procedure is somewhat similar to the one used by Duncan MacRae15 to compile a vote list. He took a list of twelve votes from the 010 News and added to it eight votes from The New Republic's list for the same two-year period. He considered those two sets of votes as subsets in his list. Apparently, there were some that were on the New Republic list that were already on the CIO list, but he grouped them with the other CIO votes because he considered the CIO's list more important (as they were more involved in the legislative process), and so was interested in the CIO and non-C10 votes as sub- sets of his final list. If, however, he had considered the two organizations'lists of equal value, he might have divided his into three subsets: those only on the CIO list, those only on the N33_ Republic list, and those on both. If the two original lists were equally valuable, then the set of votes which appeared on both would 65 seem to be more worthy of note than those which appeared on only one, and so might be sorted out into a final list. What has been done in this paper is much the same thing, except that we took the vote lists of three organizations, instead of two, and kept the overlap. However, it was also decided that the judgement of fig should be given more weight than that of the other three organizations. This was because §Q_does not officially represent an interest, ideological or other pressure group; and because it devoted its full time to watching Congressmen, whereas the ACA and the AFL-CIO watch and rate members of Congress as a sideline, largely in order to make judgements about whom to support and whom to oppose in elec- tions. Weighting 92's judgement more heavily was accomplished by deciding that ggfs selection of a vote for its list would count twice --which means that votes on 99's list, now having a double endorse- ment, would automatically be included on our final list. The question then arose of what to do if two or more or the organizations listed different votes on the same bill. Neither vote ‘was on both lists, yet the bill would seem to be of some importance, having been listed twice, so it seemed that one or both of the votes should be included. It was eventually decided that the fact that a bill is listed 'by two organizations, even though on different votes, qualifies it for inclusion, and that since the importance of each vote is an 66 indicator of the importance of the bill, only one of them needs to be used on the final list. The procedure for choosing this vote will be as follows: that vote will be selected which had the least number of "?" responses, in 9g. These are the responses in which the Senator neither voted, paired, announced a position nor responded to 3.92 poll--those in which no position was indicated. If such a response was obtained, we might reasonably guess that the Senators were apathetic about this vote. If a larger number responded this way about one vote than did about another, we may assume that the Senators, on the average, considered the former a less important vote. If one of the lists is go, then the vote is of course included automatically. If the vote on the other list has fewer "?" responses, then it is included as well. If two of the organizations, other than _C_Q_, list the same bill, the votewith fewer "?" responses is included. If §Q_and two of the other organizations all list different votes on the same bill, then the 99 vote is included, and "?" responses is also that vote from the other two which has fewer included, even if it does not have less "?”5 than the §Q_vote. Finally, we may note a special case. In the 19705, a number of attempts were made to abolish food stamps for striking workers. Amendments to this effect were proposed several times each year, attached to various bills (food stamp reform bills, agriculture appropriations, etc.). Several were listed by both ACA and COPE, so one would assume that they were an important issue. Yet the same 67 vote was never listed by both the ACA and COPE, and none of them would be eligible for inclusion on the final list under any of the provisions so far mentioned, because they involved votes on the "same" amendment to different bills. Still, it seems clear that for most practical purposes it was the same amendment in content. And COPE expressly used the word "same". On these grounds, we will choose to regard the different votes as the same, and include one of them, in accord with the procedure described above. Historical Background A further check on the soundness of the list of votes selected is to be found in the determination of whether the economic issues involved in the votes were important in the history of the period. Since this paper attempts to sample voting behavior from the Great Society era and the era immediately before it and the one immediately after it, the time frame of this study extends for several years on each side of 1963-1975. The time frame does not include all of these preceding and succeeding periods in their entirety, but rather a portion of each for sampling. Nonetheless, an overview of them in their entirety is in order so as to under- stand the background of these issues. As we noted earlier, the New Deal went through several stages, emphasizing different kinds of issues and different coalitions over them. In the last stage (1937-39), the coalitions, with their stands on the issues, took the forms that they were to have for a 68 long while afterward. Opposition to the New Deal policy of wage- and-hour legislation (or to the form it came to take), second thoughts about the pro-union aspects of the National Labor Relations Act, and impatience*with relief and other spending(with the resulting deficits) eventually drove a bloc of Democrats and most "progressive Republicans" into an alliance with those on their right, as James Patterson and others have described (see above). This loose, infor- mal grouping, beginning in about 1937, marked the beginning of the "Conservative Coalition" of Congressional Republicans and conserva- tive (eventually overwhelmingly Southern) Democrats. From this time on, most Northern and a few Southern Democrats, plus some Republicans, were known as "liberals", while most Republi- cans--both those who had in the past been known as "progressives" and those who had in the past been known as "conservatives"--and most Southern Democrats (some of whom had previously been known as New Dealers) were all known alike as "conservatives", constituting the "Conservative Coalition" in Congress. The liberals had generally supported the moves of Roosevelt since 1937, and asked for further moves in the same direction; over the years, they could be found favoring higher and more comprehen- sive minimum wages, more generous and standardized unemployment compensation, more egalitarian income tax policies, more public housing, and more deficit spending in times of high unemployment. The conservatives had often opposed Roosevelt from 1937 on, and over the years would be found generally opposing liberals on the above named issues. 69 After the 1938 elections, Republican gains augmented coali- tion membership. They did so to such an extent that the coalition was usually able, from this point until the 19605, to block passage of major liberal legislation, thus bringing an end to several years of major legislative activity. This is in part why it is commonly said that the New Deal ”ended" in 1939 or soon thereafter simply in the sense that there was a cessation of the passage of new pro- grams of major significance, and not, of course, in the sense of repealing the major parts of the New Deal. (Some programs which were originally intended to be only temporary, such as work-relief, were phased out in the next few years as the passing of Depression- era conditions elemented the need for them.) Franklin Roosevelt himself declared a few years later that he would devote his energies to winning World War 11 rather than carrying on the fight for the New Deal. The period from 1939 to 1963 saw much change in American politics, but there was a certain unity to the period as well. This was the period between the end of the New Deal and the beginning of the Great Society. There was no other such set of major social programs enacted between these two. The proposed agenda of new Social programs in 1963 was largely similar to that of 1939, with a few additions that had been made in the intervening years. This persistence of the agenda lead to a persistence of the coalitions for and against it which had taken shape by 1939. The apparent unwillingness of the electorate to tolerate further tax rate 7O increases--and, to a lesser extent, larger budget deficits--to pay for these programs was a major obstacle to the liberals and a boon to the conservatives. (The tax increase in World War II was toler- ated, but mainly for patriotic reasons; and while after it the tax was not cut to prewar levels, most of the permanent spending increase it funded was for defense, foreign aid, veterans pensions and interest, not for domestic social programs.) It became neces- sary for liberals to think of a new way to finance their programs. They discovered that economic growth could increase revenues while taxes were not increased or even decreased (in fact, lower taxes would help stimulate such growth), and so frequently became great advocates of economic growth. And it was not until economic growth reached the level that it did in the early 19605 (later encouraged further by a tax cut) that the liberals finally got their new pro- grams passed as "the Great Society". From the beginning of this period, the public was apparently unwilling to vote for those who proposed higher taxes to cover new programs. Spending on similar programs had already led to deficits. These deficits were condemned by conservatives, but liberals were inclined to argue that they seemed to stimulate the economy. How- ever, to judge by the election returns, the public had limits to its tolerance for deficits as well as limits to its tolerance for taxes, as it did not give the liberal Democrats sufficient votes to enable it to control the government. 71 World War II saw a great increase in spending and in per- sonal income taxes to pay for it. The public was willing to accept such a sacrifice for the patriotic endeavor, and by the time the war was over, it had been conditioned to accept a higher level of taxes than before. When, after the war, the ending of war-time spending allowed taxes to be reduced, they were not reduced to pre- war levels, but the public did not complain greatly. Meanwhile, depression conditions finally ended with war-time creation of jobs (and they did not return after the war, at least not in so severe a form). The increased revenues in peacetime allowed increased spend- ing, but the great bulk of these new expenditures were on defense (especially with the onset of the Cold War), foreign aid, veterans pensions and interest on the debt, with little left over for domestic social programs. In the late 19405, liberal President Truman and liberals in Congress attempted to push for new social programs (under the name of "the Fair Deal"). The liberal agenda was much the same as before the war (social security expansion, minimum-wage increases, expan- sion of public housing, etc.), with the addition of education and health insurance. The coalitions supporting and opposing it were the same, and the conservatives were still generally the larger of the two. Hence, Truman was unable to get much passed in the way of minimum-wage increases, aid to education and health insurance. The increase in the housing program was also modest. An expansion of social security coverage was enacted in 1950, but this was not a 72 great departure in principle. It was accompanied by a change of ADC to AFDC. (In 1947 and 1948 Truman also had to accept a tax cut and the Taft-Hartley Act from a Republican Eightieth Congress.) Meanwhile, the Democrats had become increasingly identified with such new social welfare programs, and since the voters were apparently averse, for the most part, to higher taxes or higher deficits, it is not surprising that the Democrats lost ground. Their Congressional margins decreased in the 1942 elections, as the Republicans broke through the 30% barrier in the Senate (as they had in the House in 1938), for the first time since before 1935 and never again sank below it. Later, in the 1946 elections, the Democrats lost control of Congress for two years. Then, after the 1950 elections, there began a period of relative Republican strength, lasting until after the 1958 elections, during which time the Repub- licans never had less than 45% of the seats in either chamber of Congress, and actually gained control of Congress with the 1952 elections. Also at this time, the Republicans gained control of the Presidency and held it for eight years (1953-61). (They did not again attain these heights until the Reagan administration.) Hence, the liberals were still generally unable to get their list of pro- grams passed, and might not have been able to do so before the 1958 elections, even without Eisenhower in the White House. During the 19503, the liberal Democrats saw that middle-class voters were generally supporting Republicans (except in the South, 73 where they generally supported conservative Democrats). Apparently the middle class voter feared that the costs of putting the liberal Democrats in office (in terms of taxes and inflation-causing budget deficits) outweighed whatever benefits they may have stood to gain from that party. In any case, the middle class was able to wield enough political power to contribute to the thwarting of liberal plans for further legislation. The liberal Democrats therefore began to appeal to the middle class for support. One example of this was Adlai Stevenson's de—emphasis of the class rhetoric which had char- acterized the campaigns of Roosevelt and Truman. Yet the liberals were still unable to offer the middle class reasons for trusting them that the middle class found convincing. Soon, however, they dis- covered a possible strategy. During the Eisenhower years, the conservatives had been able to curb spending somewhat, and so reduce the deficit (eliminating it in some years) while even allowing a moderate tax cut. They were helped in this by economic growth, which produced increased tax revenue at the old, or even somewhat reduced, tax rates. The liberals came to conclude that just as growth could allow conservatives to reduce the deficit without having to cut spending (or raise tax rates), so it could allow liberals to increase spend- ing without having to increase the deficit (or raise tax rates), thus allowing them to propose helping the poor without seeming so threaten- ing to the middle class. However, economic growth had not yet reached a high enough level to make their task easy. They began to 74 contemplate ways of actively encouraging growth by stimulating the economy . At this time Keynesian attitudes were becoming quite widespread among liberals, and according to Keynesians, there were two ways of stimulating the economy: tax cuts and Spending increases. Meanwhile, the liberals added to their agenda various pro- grams concerned with eliminating poverty, particularly among the very poor, such as the hard-core unemployed. In the period between 1955 and 1960, they first proposed such policies as area redevelopment, public works jobs and work training. This concern produced another reason for liberals to seek economic growth; it was believed by most of them that such growth would help reduce poverty and unemployment, and some of them considered that it played a more important role in doing so than such measures as job training, etc., which addressed the supposed structural causes of the problems. This brings us down to 1958. The conservative coalition was still blocking most liberal measures, while liberals were increas- ingly leaning toward economic growth as a way out of their predica- ment. Then, in the election of that year, following (and probably largely as a result of) the severe recession of 1957-58, the Democrats won landslide majorities in Congress. The election especially enhanced the ranks of Northern Democrats, and liberals among them. And of course, this meant a substantial turnover in Congressional membership. It is at this point that our study begins. This increase in liberal strength, it turned out, was not as great as it might have been; while the liberals did pass some 75 programs, they were able to pass few over Eisenhower's veto. Then in 1960, when they finally regained control of the White House, the Democrats lost their overwhelming margin of control in the House of Representatives. Thus, the liberals still had a reason to continue emphasizing economic growth as a way of paying for their programs. This was confirmed when liberal President Kennedy and his liberal allies in Congress attempted to push through the liberal agenda of programs as augmented in the 19503 under the name of "the New Frontier". They met with much frustration at the hands of the conservatives, as Truman and his allies had. The conservatives blocked passage of bills providing aid to school construction and teachers' salaries, medical assistance for the aged, and a depart— ment of urban affairs, and discouraged Kennedy from asking for others. Most of what he did get Congress to pass was relatively minor: an experimental food stamp program and some modifications in AFDC. (How- ever, he did obtain a raise in the minimum wage and expanded cover- age of it, and the passage of a bill providing for the establishment of a program of manpower training and development.) The liberals herefore considered the two Keynesian precrip- tions for stimulating economic growth--tax cuts and spending increases. Increased spending could consist of increased military spending, and some of this was sought and obtained by Kennedy. How- ever, since most liberals desired increased social welfare spending anyway, this was the sort of spending that they most often contem- plated. 76 The idea of tax cuts without increased social spending appealed to many people, such as some businessmen. The idea of increased social spending without tax cuts appealed to many liberals. The liberals of the Kennedy administration followed a third, inter- mediate course. While both tax cuts and spending increases were meant to increase growth, and so were expected to reduce deficits, both could have the short-run effect of exacerbating deficits, and consequently arousing conservative opposition. Such opposition had been successful in the past and might well be so again. However, conservatives (classical liberals) oppose high spending (whether accompanied by deficits or not) and, ultimately, favor low taxes (although they may sacrifice this good in the short run to fight deficits). Thus, Keynesians liberals were likely to find more sup- port among their conservative opposition for tax—cutting than for spending increases. Making this calculation, the Administration liberals decided that before spending money on the social programs which they, as liberals, desired, they would enact a tax-cut in the hope that the tax would stimulate the economy so as to provide revenues to balance later spending. As it happened, Kennedy got some minor tax cuts passed in 1962, and then got a few programs (involving youth employment, area redevelopment, a national service corps and aid to mass transit) passed, at least through the Senate. However, Congress did not pass his major tax-cut bill and other social programs until after his death. 77 It was Lyndon Johnson who got these measures passed. He secured the enactment of the Kennedy tax cut in 1964, which apparently did lead to increased economic growth and to increased revenues. This facilitated the new President's largely successful attempt to enact the bulk of the remaining programs on the liberal agenda, under the name of "the Great Society". Johnson had the Office of Economic Opportunity (0E0) ("War on Poverty"), an umbrella bureau containing various anti—poverty programs, established in 1964. That same year, he also got bills passed providing for aid to urban mass transit and the permanent establishment of food stamp programs to provide help for the poor in purchasing food. The passage of further legislation was aided by the Democrats' increased majorities in Congress which accompanied the landslide defeat of Goldwater in 1964 (they passed the 652 margin in the House for the first time since 1961, and in the Senate, had been at or above that percent since 1959; however, they lost much of this after the 1966 elections). Other items on the agenda that Johnson got passed, at least through the Senate, included bills providing for aid to school construction and teacher's salaries (1965); medical care for the aged ("Medicare"), financed through the social security system (1965); funds for economic development of Appalachia (1965); restrictions on air and water pollution (1965); establishment of the Departments of Housing and Urban Development (1965) and Transporta— tion (1966); subsidies to help pay for the costs of rent for low- income groups (1965, 1966, 1967); a minimum wage increase (1966); 78 more generous unemployment compensation (including federal minimum standards) (1966); and a "demonstration cities" program (1966). Johnson's failures in this regard were few, with his inability to get the right-to-work provision of the Taft-Hartley Act repealed being perhaps the most important. This victory for the liberals marked the end of this period of about twenty-five years of liberal frustration, and the start of a new period of increased government spending, as Congress enacted the first major set of government social programs since the New Deal but without a corresponding tax increase. The tax cut, and later the Vietnam War, apparently fueled an economic boom which produced enough revenue to balance the bud- get in 1969, but that was for the last time. Already, further spending growth had swollen the budget. Trends in increased spending were begun in the Johnson years which continued into the Nixon administration. The Vietnam War, going back to 1965, had been a great contributor to spending growth, but it was eventually outstripped by social welfare spending, and of course was finally wound down to a close, in the Nixon years. While the new anti-poverty and rent programs continued to be of modest size, and education and health programs maintained their moderate sizes, other social welfare spending began to grow substantially. The food stamp program grew somewhat. More importantly, Congress enacted, in 1967,.the first of three large social security benefit increases, in excess of the inflation rate. Also, in the Johnson years, AFDC grew 79 significantly, and with them, AFDC spending (in 1967, Congress made some attempt to restrict the program, but voted down a tough work requirement for mothers of school-age children while it actually liberalized the program by making some families with fathers present eligible). The food stamp program also grew at this time. At this point, Johnson, believing that the public was still not in favor of a major general tax increase (at least, not a per- manent one), chose to run deficits and cover them by expanding the money supply, thus causing inflation. A side effect of this was "bracket creep"--the pushing of people, by inflation, into a higher tax bracket. This increased their tax burden, as well as government revenue. In an attempt to deal with these programs, Congress enacted spending cuts in 1967, and some more cuts and temporary surtax in 1968, but most of the spending was bequeathed to President Nixon. He struggled somewhat to reduce the deficits. He got the surtax extended temporarily in 1969, and he did end the Vietnam War in 1973. (Overall defense spending declined as well, in this period.) However, the beginning of the winding—down of the war (1969-73) was followed by, if it did not actually cause, a recession (1969-70), which was bad for revenue. And Congress increased domestic spending, taking up the slack--and more, causing the budget to swell still further. In particular, Social Security was again increased signi- ficantly in 1969 and 1972, while spending on food stamps grew as the program was liberalized in 1969 and 1970. 80 Thus, social welfare spending increased, and to a great degree, during the Nixon years, which is rather different from what one might expect from a Republican administration. Nonetheless, social spending eventually seemed to begin to level-off. However, the liberal desire to enhance government power was not completely thwarted, as a new drive for business regulation got under way, such measures costing less than the social welfare programs and being more politically popular (most of these passed Congress and had Nixon's approval as well). This was in some ways the first big push for regulation since the Progressive Era. It was further seen that this movement was in any case qualitatively different from earlier movement for regulation. It included the environmental legislation such as air pollution legislation (as well as the older water- and land-pollution programs going back to the Johnson years); worker safety provisions such as the Occupational Safety and Health Act (OSHA, 1970); and various consumer protection measures, such as product safety legislation (1972, etc.) and a proposed Consumer Protection Agency to intervene for consumers before existing regula- tory agencies. In addition, Nixon, by means of an executive reorgani- zation order, established the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) in 1970. These proposals all seemed to be aimed rather exclusively at helping consumers or employees of a business, or victims of its pollution, rather than helping its competitors as well, as many Pro— gressive Era proposals (antitrust, etc.)--somewhat ambiguously-- attempted to do. Accordingly, the new regulation is seen as less 81 sympathetic to business than the older regulation, and there seemed to be less business support for it (although possibilities for corporate'liberalism" even here should not be ruled out). Also, these new regulations were more concerned with businesses' achiev- ing specific standards of safety, pollution, etc., for the direct benefit of the consumers and employees. This is in contrast to older regulations which were concerned with somehow limiting busi- ness's power, size or general economic discretion (as such things as antitrust laws or anti-price—cutting legislation would do) on the assumption that benefits for consumers and workers would flow from that. The rest of the economic history of the Nixon years is a complex story of inflation; recession; inflation and recession together ("stagflation"); and bracket creep; accompanied by wage/ price freezes and controls, and deficit spending, on the part of an administration originally opposed to such policies. The passing of the Great Society, the Vietnam War and the Nixon Administration all contributed to the receding of many of the issues of the late 19603 and early 19703, especially the non-economic ones, from the forefront of public attention, as this relatively liberal period came to an end and a new one arrived. The scene was now left relatively clear for the older concerns of inflation, unemployment and taxation--now generally more burdensome--to dominate the Ford administration. However, Watergate left a legacy in the form of a heavily Democratic Congress. This Congress again 82 increased the budget substantially, in spite of Ford's efforts to the contrary, passing a food stamp bill and a public works bill over his veto. In the area of labor, it passed a bill to allow common- site picketing but Ford successfully vetoed it. Also, some minor tax cuts were passed. Nonetheless a backlash against "big government" was already appearing among the public, and it soon began to influence parties. Although a Democrat was elected in 1976, he claimed to favor restraint in regard to spending and deficits. President Carter's middle course satisfied neither conservatives nor liberals. He did not greatly expand or greatly cut Spending or taxes, and what change there was did not seem to go in any obvious direction. The most important measures of his early administration seem to have been an increase in social security taxes and the beginning of deregulation in industries subject to regulatory commissions, while unions and liberals were frustrated in their attempts to modify collective bar- gaining rules in a pre-union direction. Also in this period, those conservative Republicans who found Fordtxxamoderate (in his ideological goals, economic strategies, rhetoric and/or political alliances) had a better chance to dominate their party without him in the White House, and took heart from the growing conservatism of the political atmosphere. Further, many of them had become impatient with "collecting the Democrats' taxes for them": feeling that the "conservatives" (classical liberals) must remember their goal of reducing the burdens of government, they 83 became advocates of substantial tax cuts. Such a course would not only provide a needed economic stimulus and be politically more popular than balancing the budget with low spending and high taxes, but would, by stimulating the economy, more than make up for the loss of revenue from lower rates, perhaps even balancing the budget. This latter assumption (expressed by the Laffer curve) was the same as that behind the 1964 tax cuts; along with other, different assump- tions, it formed the new "supply-side" philosophy of conservative economics. Most conservatives embraced it, including their leader, Ronald Reagan, and conservatives in Congress began taking the low- tax position on tax votes, supporting the Kemp-Roth amendment to the income tax bill in 1978 (providing a 30% general personal income-tax cut over three years). In 1980, conservatives were able to get Reagan nominated for President and elected. The political "swing to the right" of the 19703, indicated by this movement among the Republicans and Carter's moderation among the Democrats, marks the beginning of a new era. Just as the Ford years were in many ways a reversion to the pre-Great Society era-- in terms of issues and ideals, though not in policy outcomes--the succeeding years were ones in which the attempt was made to turn the clock back farther, or at least to make a strong break with the Great Society era. Furthermore, the Senatorial voting cleavages after 1980 are rather distinctive as well. 84 ENDNOTES lLee F. Anderson, Meredith W. Watts, Jr., and Allen H. Wilcox, Legislative Roll-Call Analysis (Evanston: Northwestern university Press, 1966). 2William H. Riker, "A Method for Determining the Significance of Roll-Calls in Voting Bodies", in Legislative Behavior: A Reader in Theory and Research, ed. by John C. Wahlke and Heinz Eulau, (Glen- cover, IL: The Free Press, 1959), pp. 377-387; David B. Truman, The Congressional Party: _A Case Study (New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc., l959k and Duncan MacRae, Jr., "A Method for Identifying Issues and Factions from Legislative Votes", American Political Science Review 59 (December, 1965), 909-926. 3Riker; and Anderson, Watts and Wilcox. 4Michael Foley, The New Senate: Liberal Influence on a Con- servative Institution 1959-1972 (New Haven: Yale University Press, l972),and Gary Reichard, The Reaffirmation of Republicanism: Eisen- hower_§pd the Eightijhird Congress (Knoxville: The University of Tennessee Press, 1975). 5Anderson, Watts and Wilcox. 6MacRae, "A Method for Identifying Issues and Factions": MacRae, "Some Underlying Variables in Legislative Roll-Call Votes", Public Opinion Quarterly 18 (Summer l954),l9l-195; Fred 1. Green- stein and Elton F. Jackson, "A Second Look at the Validity of Roll- Call Analysis", Midwest Journal of Political Science 7 (May, 1963). 157-166. 7Anderson, Watts and Wilcox. 8Riker; MacRae, "A.Method for Identifying Issues and Factions"; MacRae and Susan Borker Schwarz, "Identifying Congres- sional Issues by Multidimensional Models", Midwest Journal of Poli— tical Science 12 (May, 1968), 181-201; Charles D. Farris, "A Method of Determining Ideological Groupings in the Congress", Journal of Politics 20 (May, 1958), 308-388. 9Anderson, Watts and Wilcox. 10See Note 2. 85 11Riker. 12Wilder Cane, Jr., "A Caveat on Roll-Call Studies of Party Voting", Midwest Journal of Political Science 4 (August, 1960), 13Congressional Quarterly Almanac 1959-1978. (washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly, Inc., 1959-1978); Americans for Constitutional Action, ACA Index 1963-1978 (Washington, D.C.: Americans for Constitutional Action, 1963—1978); and AFL-CIO: Labor Looks at Congress has no votes in boldface type. However, since such votes were always referred to previously as "key votes", those votes called by that name in the 1978 book were considered the equi- valent of votes in boldface type.) 14Chamber of Commerce of the U.S.A. Congressional Action (Washington, D.C.: Chamber of Commerce of the U.S.A., 1978); and Michael Barone, Grant Ujifusa and Douglas Matthews, The Almanac of American Politics l972-1980 (New York: E. P. Dutton and Co., 1972-1980). 15MacRae, "Some Underlying Variables in Legislative Roll- Call Votes", pp. 191—195. CHAPTER III TESTING THE MODEL: AN ANALYSIS OF THE VOTING RECORDS Introduction Now we may turn to a consideration of the voting records. We shall first examine the data presented in the chart, then try to determine what cleavages and groups are exhibited by the votes, and finally compare our findings to the theoretical model.1 From this point on, we shall, unless we specify otherwise, use the terms "conservative" ("right") and "liberal" ("left") in the sense used in everyday conversation and the press. For the convenience of the reader, the charts tabulating the votes have the Senator's names arranged in an apparent right-to-left order (determined impressionistically, but with the results largely in accord with the evidence of the votes);2 and the votes have been grouped by issue areas, with the attempt being made to generally put related areas near each other. Another decision that was made regarding the voting lists is that all Senators who were in office for less than two years would be excluded, as they would provide too few votes for study. To facilitate the description of the votes we will divide the Senators into a few broad groups. These groups are based mainly 86 87 on conventional groupings, and are not necessarily the same as the groups in our theoretical model or the groups which we will identify after examining the voting records (although they usually do have some basis in the theory and in the voting records). They are used primarily to economize descriptions, in a more-or-less meaningful way, and too much stress should not be placed on the assignment of Senators to the groups. The first division to be made is into Republicans and Demo— crats. (James Buckley was elected as the Conservative candidate in 1970, but was admitted to the Republican caucus; Harry Byrd, Jr., a one-time Democrat who was re-elected as an Independent in 1970, voted with the Democrats on organizing the Senate. These Senators will consequently be regarded as Republican and Democrat, respect- ively.) Congressional_guarterly next divides Democrats into North- eners and Southerners, thus giving recognition to the liberal- conservative conflict between the two wings of the party. However, Cg, not wishing to get involved in actually making definitions of "conservative" and "liberal", uses a simple geographic criterion for grouping the Senators, grouping them into Northern and Southern Democrats on the basis of a definition of "the South" as consisting of the former Confederate States (Virginia, North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, Florida, Alabama, Mississippi, Tennessee, Arkansas, Louisiana and Texas) plus Kentucky and Oklahoma, and a definition of "the North" as all the other states. These are good definitions of the North and South, and we shall use them. However, the division 88 - of the Democrats into wings on the basis of those geographical groupings is inadequate for our purposes. While Northern Democrats are overwhelmingly liberal--that is, they vote on the left side of the issues in a large majority of cases--considerably less than all of the Southerners are conservative. Southern Democrats Yarborough and Kefauver are among the most liberal of all Senators, while Gore, Sasser, and Harris are close behind, and Monroney, Kerr, Fulbright and Smathers are mostly liberal. Further, most Southern Democrats first elected in or after 1966 (Hollings, Morgan, Nunn, Stone, Chiles, Ford, Huddleston, Bumpers, Johnston of Louisiana and Bentsen) are distinctly more liberal than many of those elected before 1966, and yet they are also generally more conservative than the more senior liberal South— erners mentioned above. Finally, we may note that a number of other Southerners elected before 1966 (Long of Louisiana, Ellender, Sparkman, Hill and Johnston of South Carolina) were well to the left of the old- style conservatives (although Ellender and Hill often voted with them), and most of them voted with the liberals more often. For convenience, this group would be best grouped with the liberals. This leaves us with several Senators—-Robertson, Harry Byrd Sr., and Harry Byrd Jr. (of Virginia), Ervin, Jordan (of North Carolina), Russell, Talmadge, Holland, Stennis, Eastland and McClellan, all first elected before 1966, and Allen, first elected after (plus Thurmond, when he was a Democrat, before September 1964), who had 89 voting records greatly different from the average Northern Democrat and voted often (but far from always) with conservative Republicans, while having voting records similar to each other's. They did not even constitute a majority of the pre-l966 Southerners, but they did constitute a plurality, and represented a type apparently unique to the region. They can therefore be referred to as "Old South Demo- crats". Therefore, we have among the Democrats the Old South Demo- crats; the New South Democrats (Chiles, etc.); and the liberals Northern and Southern (Yarborough, etc., plus the group including Sparkman, etc.). There are only two remaining Democrats who do not fit into these groups. These are two Northern Democrats (Lausche and Zorinsky) who voted much more often with conservative Republicans than with their liberal fellow Northern Democrats. They are not grouped with the conservative Old Southerner type of Democrat because they generally voted with the conservative Republicans, while the Old Southerners often diverged from the Republicans. Turning now to the Republicans, we can divide them into conservative and liberal wings as well. This too, is based on a conventional scheme, but the boundaries are not so clear-cut. None- theless, on the basis of their reputations and voting records, the Republicans may be divided into "conservatives" and "liberals" (these terms are primarily relative; "liberal" Republicans are not necessarily as liberal as "liberal" Democrats). On the tables, the former are those extending from Scott of Virginia to Baker, while the latter extend from Saltonstall to Case of New Jersey. 90 The votes could be arranged in one of three ways: by apparent similarity of subject, by similarity of cleavages, or by some combination of these two. In the survey in the text, they will be discussed in the first order. Then, we will attempt to group them together in the second way. For the tables, the third, middle way was chosen; this keeps together votes on ostensibly the same subject, so a Senator's stand on each one may be determined, but groups together subjects with similar cleavages, so patterns may be discerned visually. Y = a vote, pair, announcement or response to a 99 poll in favor of the proposal. X = a vote, pair, announcement or response to a‘gg poll opposed to the proposal. ? = no indicated preference, or abstention from voting to avoid a conflict of interest. C = "conservative" position, in the conventional sense,and position more favored by alleged "conservatives". than alleged "liberals". L = "liberal" position,in the conventional sense, and posi- tion more favored by alleged "liberals" than alleged "conservatives". + = position in favor of "small-government", but not more favored by alleged "conservatives" than alleged "liberals" - = position in favor of "big-government", but not more favored by alleged "liberals" than alleged "conserva- tives". ? = no known preference. 91 TABLE 1.-- Votes Used. VOTE COPE 1959 S 1555. S 1515. HR 2580. 1961 HR 3935. S 1021. S 1922. 1962 HR 10606. RE 7576. KB 11040. HR 10650. Landrum-Griffin bill: amendment to allow state regulation of labor disputes. April 3. (COLL. BARGAINING: 1959 STATE REC; Y I -) Landrum-Griffin bill: amendment to provide restraints on unions in form of "Bill of Rights" for members. April 22. (COLL. BARCNC: 1959 BILL OF HIS; Y I -) :reconsideration of previous vote. (COLL. EARGNG: April 22. 1959 RECON. s or R; Y - -) :smendment to ban secondary boycotts. (COLL . BARGNC: April 24. 1959 SECOND EOYCTS; Y I -) Education (elementary and secondary) aid bill: amendment providing aid for school construction and teachers' salaries. February 3. (1960A ELEM. AND SEC. EDUCATION; N I C) :motion to reconsider amendment providing for school construction and teachers' salaries. February 3. (19608 ELEMENTARY AND SECONDARY EDUCATION; Y I C) Social security bill: benefits for the aged. (1960 MEDICARE; N - C). amendment providing medical August 23. Minimum wage bill: amendment to narrow proposed coverage. April 19. (MIN. WAGE: 1961 COVERAGE; N I C) Education (elementary and secondary) aid bill. providing aid for operation. maintenance and construction of schools and teachers' salaries. May 25. (1961 ELEMENTARY AND SECONDARY EDUCATION; N I C) Housing program: amendment to provide a home- loan program. June 8. (1961A CEN'RL. HOUSING; Y I C) :conference report. June 28. (19613 CEN'RL HOUSING; N - C) Public welfare bill: benefits for the aged. (1963 MEDICARE; N I C) amendment providing medical July 17. amendment to delete funds to July 18. Atomic Energy funds: build new reactor in Hanford. Washington. (1962 NUCLEAR REACTORS; Y I C) Communications Satellite bill: cloture. (1962 COMSAT; N - C) Income tax bill. providing some cuts: August 14. (INCOME TAXES: passage. 1962 BILL: N I -) August 14. (X) (X) (X) (X) (X) (X) (X) £72 VOTE ACA COPE HR 11970. a"; 51. HR 5517. S 1163. S 1321. S 1831. HR 6143. 1964 HR 8363. S 2642. HR 11865. Kl: - o M 83. HR 2362. S 1648. Trade bill: amendment limiting Presidential power to cut tariff. September 18. X (1962 TARIFF POWERS; Y I -) Bill providing aid to local mass transit passage. April 4. X (1963 MASS TRANST. PASS.; N I C Youth Employment bill: amendment removing section establishing a Youth Conservation Corps. April 10. (X) (1963 YOUTH CONS. CORPS. AM.; N I C) :passage. April 10. X (1963 YOUTH EMF. BILL; N I C Bill continuing accelerated public works program: amendment to cut funds. May 1. (PUBLIC HORKS: 1963 ACCL.; N I C) Bill continuing Area Redevelopment Program passage. June 26. X (1963 AREA REDEVEL.; N I C) National Service Corps bill: passage. (1963 NATIONAL SERVICE CORPS; N I C) August 11.. 2: Bill extending Manpower Development and Training Act. especially youth training: passage. September 26. (1963 YOUTH TRAINING; N I C) Bill to aid higher education: October 21. (1963 HIGHER EDUCATION; N I C) passage. Income-tax cut bill: passage. February 7. X (INCOME TAXES: 1964 GEN. CUT; N I -) Bill establishing Office of Economic Opportunity: (OEO): passage. July 23. X (0E0: 1964 EST.; N I C) Social security bill: benefits for the aged. (1964 MEDICARE; N I C) amendment to provide medical September 2. X Hater pollution bill: amendment to delete provi- sion allowing HEW to set water quality standards. January 28. X (1965 HATER POLLUT.; N I C) Appalachian development bill: passage. February 1. X (1964 APPALACHIA; N I C) Bill providing a wide range of aid to elementary and secondary education: passage. April 9. X (1965 ELEMENTARY AND SECONDARY EDUCATION: N I C) Public works bill: amendment to cut funds. June 1. (PUBLIC HORKS: 1965 CUT; Y I C) :passage. June 1. (PUBLIC HORKS: 1965 BILL; N I C) (X) (X) (X) (X) (X) 93 VOTE CQ ACA COPE CC HR 6675. S 2213. HR 6927. HR 8283. S 2084. HR 77. 1966 HR 14012. S 985. HR 15119. S 3708. HR 13712. Social security bill: amendment to provide medical aid to the aged. July 9. X X (1965 MEDICARE AMENDMENT; N I C) :passage. July 9. X X (1965 MEDICARE BILL; N I C) Housing and Urban Dev. bill: amendment to delete rent subsidies. July 15. X X (1965 RENT SUBSIDIES; Y I C) Bill to establish Department of Housing and Urban Development: passage. August 11. X (1965 EST. HUD DEPT; N I C) OEO bill: amendment to provide for a governor's veto over certain parts of the program. August 17. X (1965 0E0 GOV'S. VETO; Y I C) :amendment to reduce funding. August 18. X (0E0: 1965 CUT; Y I C) Highway beautification bill: passage. September 16. X (1965 HIGHNAY BEAUT; N I C) Bill to repeal portion of Taft-Hartley permitting right-to~work laws: cloture. October 11. X (COLL. BARGAININC: 1965 ABOLISH RICHT-TO-HORK; N I -) Supplemental Appropriations bill: amendment to delete rent subsidies. April 27. X X (1966 RENT SUBSIDIES; N I C) Fair Packaging and Labelling bill: amendment to delete provision establishing standard weights and quantities. June 8. X (1966 STANDARD QUANT. 0N LABELS; N I C) Bill to establish national standards for unemploy- ment compensation: amendment to provide extended aid in recessions. August 8. X X (UNEMP. COMP.: 1966 RECESSION; N I C) :amendment to provide that minimum levels for maximum benefits equal one-half the average state- wide wage. August 8. (X) (X) (UNEMP. COMP: 1966 MIN. BENS; N I C) :passage. August 8. X X (UNDIP. COOL: 1966 GEN STANDS; N I C) Demonstration cities bill: amendment to delete section providing for Demonstration Cities. August 19. X X (1966 DEMONST. CITIES; Y I C) Minimum wage bill: amendment to delay increase. August 25. X (X) (MINIMUM WAGE: 1966 DELAY INV.; Y I C) (X) (X) (X) (X) 94 (0E0: 1969 CUT; Y I C) VOTE CQ ACA COPE AAP CC :amendment to narrow coverage. August 26. (X) (X) X (MINIMUM WAGE: 1966 COVERAGE; Y I C) :passage. August 26. (X) X (X) (MINIMUM WAGE: 1966 PASS; N I C) 1967 HR 9960. Independent offices and HUD appropriations bill: amendment to delete rent subsidies. September 20. X X X (1967 RENT SUBSIDIES; Y I C) S 2388. OEO bill: amendment to provide governor's veto. October 4. X X (1967 OEO COV'S. VETO; Y I C) :amendment to provide substitute public works program. October 4. X X X (0E0: PUB. WORKS AMEND. 1967); N u c HJ Res 888. Continuing appropriations bill: amendment provid- ing 52 cut in general spending. October 25. X X (GEN. SPEND'G: 1967 CUT; Y I C) HR 12080. Social Security bill: amendment to lower proposed increase. November 21. X X X (1967 SOC. SEC. INC.; Y I C) 1968 HR 15399 OEO supplemental appropriations: amendment aiding Headstart program. March 12. X X (1968 HEADSTART; N I C) HR 154144. Excise Tax bill: amendment to strike spending cut from following amendment. March 26. (X) X (X) :amendment to provide general spending cut and surtax. April 2. X (X) X (1968 SPEND CUT and INCOME TAXES: 1968 SURTAX; Y I C) S 3497. HUD bill: passage. May 28. X (1968 GEN. HUD; N I C) HR 18037. Labor/HEN appropriations: amendment to increase 0E0 budget. September 6. X (DEC: 1968 INCR.; N I C) 1969 HR 9951. Unemployment Tax bill: amendment to continue surtax. July 31. X (INCOME TAXES: 1969 SURTAX EXTENS.; N I C) S 3016. OEO bill: amendment to provide governor's veto. October 14. X X (0E0 GOV'S. VETO; Y I C) :amendment decreasing funds. October 14. X (X) 95 VOTE COPE S 2547. HR 13270. 1970 HR 14705. S 2548. HR 16916. HR 17923. HR 11102. HR 17255. HR 17755. HR 17550. 1971 SJ Res. 468. S 575. HR 8432. Food stamp reform bill: amendment to increase benefits. November 6. (FOOD STAMPS: 1969 INCR. BENS.; N I C) Tax reform bill and social security increase: amendment to increase income tax exemption. December 3. (INCOME TAXES: 1969 EXEMPT; N I -) :passage. December 16. (INCOME TAXES 1969 GEN. TAX SHIFT and 1969 SOC. SEC. INC.; N I C) Unemployment compensation bill: amendment to include migrant workers in program. February 23. (UNEMP. COMP.: 1970 MGR. HORXERS; N I C) School lunch bill: amendment liberalising provi- sions. February 24. (1970 SCHOOL LUNCH INCR.; N I C) Funds for Office of Education bill: veto override. hme30. (1970 GEN. ED. FUNDS; N I C) Agriculture bill: amendment to increase food stamp benefits. July 8. (FOOD STAMPS: 1970 INCR.; N I C) Hospital construction bill: veto override. August 18. (HOSPITAL CONSTRUCTION 1970; N I C) Air Quality standards bill: amendment to remove time limit on period when automakers can seek delays in meeting requirements on low-pollution cars. September 22. (AIR POLLUT.: APPEALS 1970; N I C) Transportation Department funds bill: amendment to delete SST funds. December 3. (1970 SST; Y I C) Social security bill: amendment to delete AFDC (PAP), trade and health provisions. December 28. (AFDC: (FAF) 1970; Y I C) Transportation bill: amendment to restore SST funds. March 3. (1971 SST; N I C) Public Works Acceleration and Regional Development bill: conference report. June 8. (PUBLIC HORKS: 1971 CONF.; N I C) :veto override. July 14. (PUBLIC BURKS: 1971 VETO; N I C) Lockheed loan guarantee bill: passage. (1971 LOCKHEED; N I C) August 2. (X) (X) X (X) (X) (X) (X) (X) (X) 96 VOTE CO ACA COPE AAP CC HR 10947. Income tax bill: amendment to reduce variance in depreciation allowance. November 15. X X (INCOME TAXES: 1971 DEPREC. ALLOW. CUT; N I C) :amendment to extend to single persons the rates applicable to married persons. November 22. (X) X (INCOME TAXES: 1971 CUT SINGLES; Y I +) S 2891. Bill to extend wage. price and related controls: passage. December 1. X (WAGE/PRICE CONTROLS: 1971 EXTENS.; N I C) S 2007. Bill to extend the OED with child care and legal services programs attached: veto. December 12. X (1971 OEO/CHILD CARE/LEG. SVCES.; N I C) 1972 S 3419. Food. Drug and Consumer Product bill: amendment to delete criminal penalties for violations of regulations. June 21. X X X (1972 PRODUCT SAFETY; N I C) S 3010. OEO bill: amendment deleting provision that would make the legal services program a separate corporation. June 26. (X) X (1972 LEGAL SVCES. CORP.; N I C) S 1861. Minimum wage bill: amendment to reduce proposed increase. July 20. X X X (X) (MINIMUM WAGE: REDUCE INCR. 1972; Y I C) S 945. No-fault auto insurance bill: motion to reconmut. August 8. X X X (1972 NO-FAULT; N I C) HR 14370. Revenue Sharing bill: amendment to adopt distri- bution formula favoring urbanized states. September 6. X (X) (X) (REV. SHAR.: 1972 DIST. FORM.; N I C) :amendment on funding levels. requiring annual approvals. September 7. X (X) (x) (REV. SHAR.: 1972 FUNDS; N I C) :passage. September 12. (X) X X (REV. SHAR.: 1972 PASS; N I C) S 3939. Highway bill: amendment to allow trust funds to be used for railroads. September 19. X (1972 HIGHNAY FUNDS FOR MASS TRANSIT; N I C) HR 1 Social Security bill: motion to kill amendment establishing Family Assistance Program with higher benefits than Nixon version. October 3. X (AFDC (PAP): 1972; Y I C) S 3970. Consumer Protection Agency bill: cloture. October 3. X (1972 CONSUM. PROTECT. AGENCY; N I C) 97 VOTE C0 ACA COPE CC HR 161310. S 1081. S 425. S 2589. 1974 HR 7824. S 2727. S 354. S 2984. S 1539. S 3458. Bill to raise debt ceiling and authorize presi- dential spending cuts: passage. October 17. (GEN. SPENDG.: 1972 CUT; Y I C) Highway bill: amendment to use highway trust funds for mass transit. March 14. (1973 HIGHWAY FUNDS FOR MASS TRANSIT; N I C) Alaskan pipeline bill: amendment to deny right- of-way for pipeline pending further environmen- tal study. July 13. (ALAS. PIPE: 1973 DELAY; N I C) :amendment to bar judicial review of the envir- onmental aspects of the bill and give permis- sion to begin construction. July 17. (ALAS. PIPE.: 1973 BAR JUD. REV.; Y I C) Strip mining bill: amendment to prohibit surface coal mining where government owned mineral but not surface rights. October 8. (1973 STRIP MINING; N I C) Emergency Energy bill: fuel rationing amendment. November 15. (1973 urlosmc: N . C) :motion to recommit to conference. February 1974. (1974 GEN. ENERGY; N I C) Bill to establish Legal Services corporation: cloture. January 30. (1974 LEGAL SVCES. CORP.; N I C) Minimum wage increase: passage. March 7. (MINIMUM WAGE: PASS INCR. 1974; N I C) No-fault insurance bill: passage. May 1. (1974 NO-FAULT; N I C) Council on International Economic Policy bill: motion to kill amendment giving President stand- by power to control wages and prices in selected industries under certain circumstances. May 1. (WAGE PRICE CONT.: 1974 SELECT; N I C) :motion to kill amendment continuing Cost of Living Council and giving President power to enforce price agreements after decontrol. May 1. (HAGEIPRICE CONT.: PRICE ACREE./CLC 1974; N I C) Education bill: amendment to change formula for distributing aid to poor children. May 15. (1974 EDUCATION FORMULA; Y I C) Food stamp bill: motion to kill amendment to and food stamps for strikers. July 22. (1974 FOOD STAMPS FOR STRIKERS; N I C) (X) (X) (X) (X) X (X) (X) X (X) X X (X) (X) X (X) (X) (X) 98 VOTE CQ ACA COPE S 707. HR 1449. HR 10710. 1975 HR 2166. HR 4222. HR 5900. S 2711. S 622. 1976 HR 5247. S 354. S 3136. HR 9803. S 3201. S 2872. Consumer Protection Agency bill: cloture. September 19. X (1974 CONSUM. PROTECT. AGENCY; N I C) Community Services Bill: amendment to phase-out 0E0. December 11. X (0E0: 1974 PHASE-OUT; Y I C) Bill to give president powers to negotiate tariff reduction: cloture. December 13. X (1974 TARIFF POUERS; N I -) Bill to reduce personal and corporate income taxes and provide social security bonus: con- ference report. March 26. X (INCOME TAXES: 1975 GEN. CUT.; N I -) School lunch and child nutrition bill: veto override. October 7. X (1975 SCHOOL LUNCH; N I C) Bill to allow common-site picketing: passage. November 19. X (COLL. BARGAINING 1975: COMMON-SITE PICXETING; N I -) Highway bill: amendment to allow funds to be used for mass transit. December 12. X (HIGHHAY FUNDS FOR MASS TRANSIT 1975; N I C) Energy bill (providing stand-by fuel rationing powers. fuel efficiency standards. etc.): conference. December 17. X (1975 GEN. ENERGY; N I C) Public Works bill: veto override. February 19. (PUBLIC NORXS: 1976 lsT; N I C) No-fault auto insurance bill: motion to kill. March 31. X (1976 NO-FAULT; Y I C) Food Stamp Reform bill: passage. April 8. X (FOOD STAMPS: 1976 REFORM; N I C) Bill providing aid to child day care: veto override. May 5. (1976 CHILD DAY CARE; N I C) Public Norks Jobs bill: veto override. June 8. X (PUBLIC HORKS: 1976 2ND; N I C) Federal Energy Administration bill: amendment setting energy conservation standings for construction of new buildings. June 15. (1976 ENERGY CONSV. BUILDINGS; N I C) :amendment establishing office to gather energy information. June 15. (1976 ENERGY INFO.; N I C) (X) (X) 99 VOTE CQ ACA COPE CC HR 10612. S 3219. HR 8532. HR 14232. HR 4876. S Con Res 19 S 275. HR 5885. HR 7555. Income tax bill: amendment to end deferral of taxes on unremitted earnings and profits of foreign subsidiaries of U.S. firms. June 29. (X) (INCOME TAXES: 1976 FOR CORP. CRED.; N I C) :motion to kill motion to recommit bill so as to remove all provisions except for those pro- viding individual reductions and credit. August 5. X (INCOME TAXES: 1976 PERS. BENS. ONLY; Y I C) Clean Air bill: amendment to eliminate the requirement that unpolluted air be kept that way. August 3. X (AIR POLLUT: 1976 NONDEGRADATION; Y I C) :amendment to move date of compliance up from 1980 to 1979. August 5. X (AIR POLLUT: 1976 EASTEN; N I C) :amendment deleting provision to relax tolerance limits for nitrous oxide. August 5. (X) (AIR POLLUT: I976 TOUGNTEN; N I C) Antitrust revision bill: amendment to make tougher. September 6. X (1976 ANTITRUST; N I C) Bill appropriating money for Departments of Labor and NEW bill: veto override. September 30. X (1976 LABOR/HEW DEPT. FUNDS; N I C) Economic Stimulus Tax-Cuts bill: amendment to permanently reduce lower-bracket personal income tax rates. April 27. X (INCOME TAXES: 1977 PERS. CUT.; Y I C) Economic Stimulus spending bill: amendment to cut spending on public works. May 2. X (PUBLIC WORKS: 1977 CUT; Y I C) :passage. May 4. x (PUBLIC WORKS: 1977 PASS; N I C) Budget bill: amendment to cut housing funds. May 4. (1977 GEN'RL HOUSING; Y I C) Farm-food bill: amendment to retain requirement of partial payment for food stamps. May 24. (FOOD STAMPS: 1977 PURCB REQUIREMENTS; Y I C) Water Resources/User Fees bill: amendment to authorize construction of a new water project. June 22. X (1977 WATERWAYS; N I C) Labor/HEW funds bill: amendment to require OSHA to submit an economic impact statement with its regulations. June 28. (OSHA: 1977 ECON. IMPACT; Y I C) (X) (X) (X) x (x) 100 VOTE CO ACA COPE AAP CC S 1811. ERDA funding bill: amendment to cut funds for Clinch River Breeder reactor. July 11. X X (1977 NUCLEAR REACTORS; Y I C) HR 3744. Minimum wage bill: amendment to provide youth sub-minimum wage. October 7. (X) X (MINIMUM WAGE: 1977 YOUTH SUB-MIN; Y I C) HR 93946. Social Security bill: motion to kill amendment to increase taxes and decrease employers' tax base. November 14. X X X (1977 SOC. SEC: FIN; N I C) :amendment to raise age at which eased restric- tions on outside earnings take effect in another amendment. November 14. X (1977 SS: EARN. LIM.; N I C) 1978 S 2493. Airline deregulation: amendment to loosen regu- lation. April 19. X (1978 AIRLINE DEREG.; Y I C) :amendment to give displaced workers hiring prio- rity instead of compensation. April 19. X (1978 AIRLINE JOBS PROJECT; Y I C) 5 Con Res 80. Budget bill: amendment to cut budget by $25 billion. April 25. X (X) (1978 GENR'L SPEND. CUTS; Y I C) HR 8309. Waterway user fees/water projects bill: amendment to impose user fees. May 3. X X (1978 WATERWAY USER FEES; Y I C) HR 8410. Bill to revise NLRA to facilitate organizing of unions: cloture. June 14. x x x x (COLL. BARGAINING: 1978 NLRA; N I C) HR 27777. Bill to establish National Consumer Cooperative bank: passage. July 13. X X (NAT. CONSUM. COOP. BANK. 1978; N I C) MR 11445. Small Business/OSHA bill: amendment to exempt small businesses with good safety records from OSHA. August 2. X X (OSHA: 1978 SMALL BUSINESS EXEMPT; Y I C) HR 12936. Housing bill: cut funds. August 7. X X (1978 GEN'RL HOUSING; Y I C) HR 13511. Income tax bill: amendment to cut taxes further for lower income brackets. October 6. X (X) (X) (INCOME TAXES: 1978 PERS. CUT; N I C) :amendment to cut individual tax rates 30! over the next three years. October 6. (X) X (X) (INCOME TAXES: 1978 KEMP-ROTH; Y I C) 101 VOTE HR 5285. CO ACA COPE :amendment to cut corporate taxes. October 10. (X) (INCOME TAXES: 1978 CORP. CUT; Y I C) Medicare and Hospital Cost Containment bill: motion to kill amendment to aid hospitals and limit earnings. October 12. X (1978 HOSPITAL COST CONT.; N I C) Humphrey-Hawkins economic stimulus bill: amend- ment to weaken provisions requiring reductions of inflation to 31 by 1983. and 02 by 1988. October 13. (PUBLIC WORKS: 1978 NUM.-EAW. INFL.; N I C) (X) (X) CC ll)2 TABLE 2.--Roll-Call Votes. mvcsm .oaoo mu:\tonam .mncou oup>cmm panopuoz me_e.oc» ease» ucoum was: .c-ucou "goes; poonom .co=~ ”goes; possum .ncou .moo>m pound stag use e_.gu ouo> m.>o¢ owe .moosm .oom \ocoo.v.¢euxcwc I. assuomusa uau .toe_ you .umw 0E0 msw— mom— mom. mom— mum— Osm— fiWWap as. was. oom— soo— wo— pump eso— oom— moo— mam— coop C C (Va.) H. Byrd Sr. C C (Va.) H. Byrd Jr. Robertson Stennis C C C C C C C ? C C C Eastland C L C C C C C McClellan Allen C C C C C C C C Russell C C C C C C C C Holland Ervin C L C C C C L C C C Jordan (N.C.) Talmadge Scott (Va.) Thurmond C C C C C C C C C C C C C C Tower Helms Goldwater Curtis C C C C C C C C C Simpson Butler Buckley Garn Laxalt C C C C C C C C C C C C Hilliams (Del.) Bennett L C C C C C C Dominick C C Hickenlooper c c c c c c c c .c c c c c c Hansen C C C Fannin Hruska Mundt ? Hatch Bartlett (0kla.) Murphy Gurney C C 1(13 mvcou .unoa :u:\con~a .mocou uu.>com .ueo.~oz neecaoch ease» «Loom coo: .528 2.2.3 32.3 .coe. “goes; possum .ntoo .muusm poms; ocuu hen v—ynu ouo> n.>ow cue .moo>m .ooa \ocou.u__eu\9uo T uso-omuaa oau .co:~ oau .umw 0E0 oka— moo— awo— muo— cum— m3. 3. £2 amo— swap oo— pum— cum— moo— moo— meo— can. Mechem Dworshak Martin McClure C C C C C C C Jordan (1d6-) Bridges Cotton C C C C C C C C C C Miller Allott Capehart Brock Schoeppel Dirksen C C Lausche Zorinsky Case (S.Dak.) Wiley Lugar L C C C C L Young (N.Dak.) Hayakawa Schmitt Wallop Roth C C Carlson Morton C Griffin Domenici Dole Bush C Baker Danforth C Saltonstall Bellmon C C C C L C L Pearson Stevens 1114 mucsm .oamo 3w:\coaom .mucou oovscom paeo.o~z oe.e.~c» ease» ocean use: .c_u:ou 22.3 possum .coe_ ”cocoa _oogum .ncou .muosm peas; 9.8 58 3.5 ooo> u.>oa cum .moo>m .mom \ocau.u—.:U\Cuo uaouomuem emu r. .coc_ usu .umu asap moa— awo— muo— cum— «— osm— awo— soo— co— paw— «sm— acm— woo— moo— voo— C C C C C C Ellender Hill C C Nunn Stone Bentsen Chiles C Hollings Morgan DeConcini Spong Cook Packwood Boggs Fong L C C C C C C L L C L C L Beall Sr. Beall Jr. Taft Saxbe L L C L C L C C C Kuchel L C C Cooper C L Smith (Me.) Prouty Aiken L C L C L C L Chafee L C L C L C Scott (Pa.) Heicker Percy C Hatfield Keating Stafford Schweiker Heinz Mathias L L L L L C L Javits Goodell 105 woe—i Jame 3w:\coaea .macou oo.>com poeo.uoz ue.e_ucp gaze» ocean coo: .e.ueou £25.. possum .coe_ ”goes; possum .ncou .muo>m —ooom menu Ago opveu coo» m.>ow cuc .mou>m .mom \ocnu.up.su\ouo j 3932... LS .cue. as as CEO cum— noo— nea— mum— cum— a— mum— meow soo— ma— pum— tum— aco— camp mwop coa— C ? Brooke L ? L L L Case C L L L ? C L Sparkman Johnston (S.C ) Johnston (La.) Long (La.) L L Fulbright Smathers Frear C O'Mahoney Hickey Ford Huddleston Bumpers L L L L Gore Moynihan Edmondson Kerr L Monroney L L L L L L L L L L L L L L R. Byrd (u.va.) Cannon Bible L L L Anderson (N.Mex.) Chavez L L L L L L L Hayden L L L L Randolph Montoya Johnson L L L L Sasser Bass L ? L L L L Symington L Long ('40.) ? L L L ? Mansfield Metcalf L L L L L L L Murray 106 mezzo .uaoo zuzxcoaoa .mncou uo.>cum pseovuax oe.c.oc» eu=o> ocean use: .e.ocou £83 poogom .coe. "gonad poo‘om .acou .moosm p.904 menu Asa up—gu ooo> m.>ou cue .moosm .uoa \ocou,u—_;u\cuo “so-omeea you .coe. you .umu 0E0 muo— non. noo— moa— muo— osm— We: a. 22 moo— mom— oo— pump cun— auap moo— mco— voo— Eagleton Gravel L L LLLL LLLLL Harris LLLL L L C L L L LLLLL Church Melcher Durkin McIntyre Biden Leahy Dodd L L LLLL L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Hartke Proxmire Burdick Haskell Riegle Anderson (Minn.) L L LLLLL LLLLL Magnuson L L L Jackson McGee L LLLLL L ? L L lnouye Long (Haw.) Matsunaga L L L L L L LLLLL Williams (N.J.) Moss L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Bayh Pell L Pastore LLLLL L Ribicoff J. Kennedy (Mass.) Glenn Stevenson Gruening LLL LLL LCL LLL LLL L L L L L Bartlett (Alsk.) Morse Hart (Colo.) 1117 «mead .uooa muzxconua .mncou oo.>com passion: ue.eaoc» ease» acoum coo: .=_o¢ou "guess possum .coe. "cocoa pooeom .ocou .moo>m paaom otao son u_.gu ouu> m.>ow ow: .moosm .mom \ocou.vp_su\omo 1: sso-om.za asu .coe— sag .omu 0E0 ena— moo— noo— coo— mso— eso— _HMNG. as. was. mea— noo— oa— pum— vsm— aco— wea— moo— voo- L L L L L L L McGovern Abourezk Cranston Hughes L L L L L L McCarthy Green LCL L L L L L L L L L LL r r e e 0.. t r. SEE Hlb 890 The BEN Carroll L L L L L L Young (0-) Tunney Smith (Mass.) Muskie Hathaway L R. Kennedy (N.Y.) Hetzenbaum McNamara Humphrey L L L L L L L L L Mondale L L L L L L Tydings L Nelson ? L L L E. Kennedy (Hass.) Sarbanes Kefauver L L L L L Yarborough Clark (1a.) Culver L ? L L L L Hart (Mich.) Douglas Clark (Pa.) 108 .ueou umou poo.nmo: .uoscumcou puu.amoz ——.m oceu_umt nanosecoec ocoowuo: mm—u—u .umcoemo ca: .eow .uan 9:: .uwu oc—mso: —.t:oo mo_m—mn:m «so: apostom eo.uoo=vu eovuoosom Logo.: ocean .nu .cuu eo.uuosom acumeouom veg agouequpw mum— asap mco— emo— «cap ~oa— mo— woop moo. .ummo_ cam. o_wo. .lhgg. 48. moo. lawns. eno— noop chap moo— _oo_ momm— o¢.ooo.cou ..3.o. s.x:..: .yop—oa toys: eueooo» e33: eo.yuoeco -eo n—ouoo< acoyuaou coupooz mum. snap muo— amo— up nua— Nsm— wso— -mp .... HUM... .a. ~... "sop asap num— muo— moa— usa— usu— asap cum— «no— cap (Va ) c H. Byrd Sr. H. Byrd Jr. Robertson Stennis C C C L (Va.) Eastland McClellan Allen C L Russell Holland Ervin C Jordan (N.C.) Talmadge Scott (Va.) Thurmond Tower Helms Goldwater Curtis Simpson Butler L C Buckley Garn Laxalt C Williams (Del.) Bennett Dominick Hickenlooper C C C C Hansen Fannin Hruska Mundt Hatch Bartlett (0kla.) Murphy Gurney 121 Rev. Shar. m . Mun— $262158 Air Pollut. .yQmeu mam: nymom ypoEm yucca. .eoou yymeoc» nus: .23. .36... «no. .ymeuc» was: .11. man. moeou .53. .3... 3858. hmm unmeau .53... 2.... hope: 53.8 .3.... .3.... .8... eoeaoop e33: eo.yooocmoo lg: m—oooo< «coyoooc coo—us: ano— usu— wha— «so— a— noo— Num— ~nm— ~no— :3. m... a. .8. asap asap num— muo— mou— usa— unm— unm— unm— m... 8. Mechem Dworshak Martin McClure Jordan (Ida.) Bridges Cotton Miller Allott Capehart C Brock Sc hoeppel Dirksen Lausche Zorinsky Case (S.Dak.) Wiley cccccc cccccc C L L L C L Young (N.Dak.) Hayakawa Schmitt Wallop Lugar Roth Carlson Morton Griffin Domenici Dole C C Bush C Baker Danforth Saltonstall Bellmon C Pearson C L Stevens 122 s a .I A OSHA .yoeoxu mmoe -.mou ppoEm yoooE. .coou y.meuch mun: mono. screwy: mung luwmeoch «as: ; nuns r e M v.95... .5... .3... 3858. c... yomeou .53... 3.... . . a... m 32.63.... .33.. .3.... .yo—poa coyo: coemoop :uymoz eoyyouacooo Is: m—ooom< Air Pollut. acoyoouz coo—ooz unm— sno— muo— asap mm— moo— Num— wump «ea. .3. m... .3. .8. m~o— num— nua— muo— mum— usa— eso— eso— una— Nem— oo— Ellender Hill C Nunn Stone C C C C C Bentsen Chiles C L C C C L L Hollings C C Morgan C Spong DeConcini Cook C C ? L L L C Packwood Boggs Fong L Beall Sr. L C Beall Jr. Taft L C Saxbe Kuchel Cooper Smith (Me.) Prouty Aiken Chafee L L L L C Scott (Pa.) Weicker Percy C 7 L L L L L L C C C C C Hatfield Keating L C L C C Stafford Schweiker Heinz C Mathias L L L L Javits Goodell 1J213 V e R Alas. M s o Shar. & mm>o¢.voe.c3 Air Pollut. .ygonu .moe -.mou ..o5m yous... . Sou y.meocy awe: mono. moszu.: anon .ymeucy was: was. moeou .33... .y... E “.852... yum yomeou ac.e.x o—cym ya... 43:... :13... .yo..o. toyao cuemooy 5...... copyemecooo acoz m—eooo< «coyoooz coo—ooz usa— usu— mso— nun— a— noo— msmp ~sm— ~sm— .... m... . .a. ~... num— nsop asa— mum— muo— usa— usa— osm— eso— HUN... .3. L Brooke Case Sparkman Johnston (S.C.) L Johnston (La ) Long (La.) Fulbright Smathers Frear O’Mahoney Hickey Ford Huddleston Bumpers Gore Moynihan Edmondson Kerr Monroney 4. L R. Byrd (H.Va.) Cannon Bible Anderson L (N.Mex.) Chavez Hayden Randolph Montoya C Johnson Sasser Bass L Symington Long (Mo.) Mansfield C Metcalf Murray 124 An .yoeoxm «woe W 1.39:; an: L L C L L C C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L “.29.: .58 :m— L L C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L 3.2.5....— mso— C C C C C L C C C L C C L C L L L ? L L L C C mac: :2 I. C L C L C L C L L C L L L C L L L L 23:... :23; o— L 1 C L L C L c L L o C L L c L L L L amen L C L L C L L L C L L C C L L L L L L .ymcmsh was! mug ._ was; 22 C L ? C L L C C L L L L L L L L L L C .r mm “‘63“ NNOP 9. L 9. C C C C L L L L L L C L L L L C .50.. tau:— Nsm— C L ? C C L C C C C ? L L C L 7 L L L 902...qu :2 C L C C L C C C C C C C L L C C C C C :2 C L C C C C L C L L L L C L C C C C C hmm as C L C C C L C C C L 1. L L C L C C C C yous”. Nap L L L L C L L C L L L L L C C C 9:5: nvsum nap ? L l L L L L ? L L L ? L L C L L L L L n 50—00 23 C C L L L 9. L L C C ? C L C L C L L 1. Cali AP $08.37;; p.3— L C L L L C L L L L L L L L L L L .yoeoa him—z moo— L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L .yo—poa Loam: mm: L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L . cocoon-h camp C C C L C ? L ? L C L L L C C L L L L ? L L t 10. :32: @3— C C L L C ? L ? L C L L L C C L C L L L L C C 1 % 532.86.... T 1:02 oso— L L L L L L L L L L L L L L ? L C L L L L L L i A $323 Ea— L L L L L L L L L L L ? L L L o ? L L whouuumc s sm— . + . . + + ? + + . + + + . . o. + + . + + + . .5293. 8.. L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L l \d ) ~ ) “ ks n n .m J. m h. m. ) W ( m. w a m. n n e e n n a g S f e 0 g L 0 r. r r 1K TI 0 0 n H a m e f n S n f. t .l S .n e n V. e .l C 1.. e S S 0 e l\ n d r O n n .l e e e .l C h .1. t n y (K m .1 e .l r. U S e V. u .1. 0 C e n e n «I e l v r r C .K n e h d t x d .K 0. e n .K .W u 9 S .I S h .I t .l K n V e t S wouMirIduwrmwsnmmc mmtisyisb emu... E G H C W. m R B L D m P B ”m R A M h k l. L m m M M W. h m J. m S .M. k M Hart (Colo.) 0 Rev. Shar. 125 Air Pollut. .yoonu «no: -.mou p—osm . .yoeoxm .eoou y'aeocy mus: mono. mezzo—z a... .ymeoc» moo: was. «too. .eLo. .ym.a 335.3 hmm yomeou 33...... 2.... _H a... sensor... 333.. .33.... .yo—poa coy-3 cocooo» e33: -eoyyooocmoo 188 m—oooo< neoyooog coo—ooz usa— sump mnop num— @— moa— Nnup mum— msm— puop m... a. Nom— asa— nna— muo— mom. mum. usa— usu— usa— enm— _N... 8. L L L C C C 4. (0.) E. Kennedy (Mass.) R. Kennedy (N.Y.) Sarbanes Smith (Mass.) Metzenbaum Neuberger Muskie Yarborough Clark (1a.) Culver Hart (Mich.) Douglas Clark (Pa.) McGovern Abourezk Cranston Hughes McCarthy Green Brewster Engle Carroll Young Tunney Hathaway McNamara Humphrey Mondale Tydings Nelson Kefauver 14265 .m3t..y:< seem no-ou .lfieou .y-z .yooyoca you oeypcy< .oo¢-oo oeypcye myommm yuouocm m—oooy co .ye-oo venue-am August ...o.3t. .538 ypouu o: .oyeu uneven ..=.o..3. .sueou 3.35 nucoeu .euu .=.=3...¢ .m :82 now.“ _m .uu... r. .meoyxu usa— usu— unm— osm— ~50— cum, .sta— and... c... .1.... o... usa— man— may num— cau— nua— pso— (Va.) H. Byrd Jr. (Va.) H. Byrd Sr. Robertson C L L L L C Stennis Eastland McClellan Allen C Russell Holland Ervin C L Jordan (N.C.) Talmadge C C C Scott (Va.) Thurmond C Tower Helms C C Goldwater Curtis Simpson Butler C Buckley Garn Laxalt Williams (Del.) Bennett C C Dominick Hickenlooper Hansen C C C Fannin Hruska Mundt Hatch C C Bartlett (Okla.) Murphy Gurney .1237 Wage-Price ymoLy—yc< some oo-ou .538 you ..o..ot. 3o. oc....< .uoulua oeyyc.< myoyom yooooca n.0ouo co ..=aoo agave... aoeom< .yooyoco .someou y—oou oz .oyeu aucoeu ..=.o..3. .smeou aucueu nausea .eou .e.eo...¢ uou \uoco< oo.cc .8... .meuyxu Control uno— amo— muo— oxap mum— comp eso— [Inha— .um... .... Us. asap asap WNW... .m. n... .... mxo— pump Mechem Dworshak Martin McClure L Jordan (Ida.) Bridges Cotton C Miller C Allott Capehart C Brock Schoeppel Dirksen Lausche Zorinsky Case (S.Dak.) Wiley Lugar C L Young (N Oak.) Hayakawa Schmitt Wallop Roth Carlson Morton C Griffin Domenici Dole C Bush C Baker Danforth Saltonstall Bellmon Pearson C Stevens 128 Wage-Price Control ymocy—yc< xeou oo-ou .533 .yuz .yuuyoca you ocy—c—< ..o¢-oo 2. I... 1...... .38... ..oa~u co .53.. 2.3.5.. aoeoo< .yooyoca .someou y—o-u o: .oye. aucoeu moeyv—.ou .oaeou uneven aucoew .euu 2.8.... uou \ooco< so... you—om .mcoyxu unm— asap unm— mum— ~50— coop :2 [:2 1m... :2 [:2 usa— usa— m... .2 :2 :2 muo— pum— C Ellender Hill Nunn Stone C Bentsen Chiles L C Hollings Morgan Spong DeConcini Cook C C Packwood Boggs Fong C Beall Sr. C C Beall Jr. Taft Saxbe Kuchel Cooper Smith (Me ) Prouty Aiken C Chafee C C C C L Scott (Pa.) Heicker Percy Hatfield Keating Stafford C Schweiker Heinz L L Mathias Javits Goodell 129 Hage-Price Control umzsu_uc< scum ao-ou .523 .32 .uuouosn sea uc——L.< .nuzuoo ocvpg.< hummum uuzvosa upona. co .ucoac vL-vcoum aucuo< .uuouogs .namcou apnea 0: .o»:_ gunmen mu=.u__=m .>mcou ausocm ungocm .cuu oc.co...¢ ugu \vogu< ouvsa woo—om .mcuuxu mum— osm— asap mum— ~50— oom— chu— LINK.— film... e... .um... eso— usa— NH”... so. a... eta. mum— ps¢p C L C Brooke Case Sparkman Johnston (S.C.) L L L L Johnston (La.) Long (La.) Fulbright Smathers Frear O'Mahoney Hickey Ford Huddleston Bumpers Gore Moynihan Edmondson Kerr Monroney L C L C L R. Byrd (H.Va.) Cannon Bible L Anderson (N.Mex.) Chavez L L Randolph Montoya Hayden Johnson Sasser Bass Symington Long (Mo.) Mansfield Metcalf L L Murray 1:3(l Hage-Price Control .mst...c< scum colou .ssmcou .uaz .uuouOLa now oc_psv< .ao¢-oo o:.—L.< 588.88: «_uaa. co ..=.=c vague... sucuo< ..uo.oca .nsmcou u—aou 0: .ouc. magnum moc_u—_:a .sucou sugoeu awsocu .cou u=.=o.... ado \oogo< ou.eg ans—om .mco.xu asap muo— muo— asa— -o— coo— 'No— film... ..m.a. c... film... eso— osm— HUN... .0. a... .Na. mma— psa— L L Eagleton Gravel Harris L Church Melcher Durkin McIntyre L Biden Leahy Dodd ? C L Hartke Proxmire Burdick Haskell Riegle Anderson (Minn.) L L I. L Magnuson Jackson McGee Inouye Long (Haw.) Matsunaga L L L Hilliams (N.J.) Moss L L L Bayh Pell L L Pastore Ribicoff J. Kennedy (Mass.) Glenn L Stevenson Gruening Bartlett (Alsk.) Morse Hart(Colo.) 1J3]. Rage-Price Control umaguwucd scum 30.09 .528 .uoz .uoouoca non uc——L—< .uuuluo mc——L.< s....m ..:uota m—unoa co .ucnac uuaucoum Aucoa< .uuouOLa .ssucou ._=.. oz .o»c~ magnum ma=.u_.=o .>m:ou Augueu 3.55 .59 ae.=o_..¢ gag \uouo< ou.ga «um—om .mcouxu oump asap who— who— ~50— noo— e... ..n~m. ..m~o_ v... run... asu— asap HUM... no. n.9— «so. mam— pum— L McGovern Abourezk C Cranston L Hughes McCarthy Green Brewster Engle Neuberger Carroll Young (0.) Tunney C Smith (Mass.) Muskie L Hathaway R. Kennedy (N.Y.) Metzenbaum McNamara L C Humphrey Mondale Tydings L L L L Nelson ? E. Kennedy (Mass.) Sarbanes ' Kefauver Yarborough Clark (1a.) Culver L L Hart (Mich.) Douglas Clark (Pa.) 132 moon Lon: mazgouu: «susguuo: .v:u2< «ago: .aan ”cue ——_n .aeu suao> .mngou .mcou guao> .pasoeox uuu< n.3uupoan< .cs 32.5. l .28 .3 .25 5 .n .m— 0 u a... C H .28 b m :3 .3 r. 32 i3 .55 "mm .5... .8. .8» 3:... 5 =8 .3 0L8~ 098 .8“ .35 .uom .uom ..=u acne. 7.38 .xugam a .3. .ueoam ms uzu mm .3 328 km”. .3 osm— usu— swo— noo— noo— «cop moop cum— “sa— sum— chap osm— psa— —~o— mom— mwop noop sump sump aco— mom— ma. moo— wsmp awa— soo— C C C (Va.) H. Byrd Sr. H. Byrd Jr. Robertson L C C C C C C C C C C C C (Va.) C C C C C L L L L L C L C L C C C C C C C L L C C L L C C C C C C C C L C L C Stennis ? C C C 9 C L L L L C C C L C C L ? ? L L C L ? Eastland McClellan Allen C C C ? L L C L C L C C Russell Holland Ervin L C C L L L L L C C C L L C C C L L L C L L L L L C C L C L L L L L L L L L L Jordan (N.C.) Talmadge CLL CLL C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C L C C C 7 L C C C L C C C C C C C C C C C L C L Scott (Va.) Thurmond C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C L Tower Helms C Goldwater Curtis C C C C L C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C Simpson Butler L Buckley Garn C C C C C C C C C C Laxalt C C C C C C C C L C C C Hilliams (Del.) Bennett C L C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C Dominick C C C Hickenlooper L C C C C C C ? C L cccc cccc ccc.c Hansen C L C C C C C C C C C C C C C ? Fannin C C ? C Hruska Mundt Hatch ? C Bartlett (Okla.) Murphy Gurney 1433 wood gum: moguouax 32:35 .u=.e< .xto: .aaa "cuo ——.n .nau gaze» .mnsou .mcou gaze» .—u>uvu¢ oos< ..gu...aa« .—b:~ ”3a:utsz in. mung use 5 .o=~ .n .... 0 H 30> .n . um Leo. N :3 uau rll pout .n.. .cL-u "mm .c—u .uum .uom .....m x.. so. .. .Loc~ .uom .uom Cup: .93 Jon muse ucoam p.5cuu .xusam a .3. .ueaam .3. .a. .....a .3. 9 m Spend asa— sam— nom— nom— nam— nam— moo— nuo. usa— sum— @50— ema— psa— psa— moa— moo— nea— una— Nua— awo— “oo— _wao. mom— Ngu— man— “no. Mechem Dworshak Martin ? C C C C McClure C C C C C C C C C L C Jordan (Ida ) Bridges Cotton C C C C L C C C C C C C C C C C C C C C L C C C C C C Miller C C C Allott Capehart C C L C Brock Schoeppel C C C C Dirksen C C Lausche L Zorinsky Case (S.Dak.) Hiley CLCCCL CLCCCL L C C C C C C C C C C C Lugar C C C C ? L L L C C C L Young (N.Dak.) C C 9. C L C c C C 7. c C 7. c C C L C a w t a L p u .1 o 1 Va m 1| m c a S ”I C C C C C C C Roth C C C C Carlson Horton C C C C C C C L C ? L C C C Griffin L C C C C C C C Domenici Dole Bush LCCLCCLC‘.’ C C ? c c c “c Baker C L L Danforth Saltonstall Bellmon ? C C C L L C 7 C C L C C C C L L C C C L C C ? C Pearson L L C L C L C Stevens 134 38 Law: .3353; @8— c c L c L ? L L C L c L c L L c c c Eastman: :2 CLCCLC L L c CLL CLLCCC 6:95 muse: .aan "OUO Nap C C L L L L C L L L L :3 .3 53> nap C C C L C L L L C C L L L 69.3 .28 5:0» 32 C c L c C L c C c C c c .—o>ovu¢ 35¢ nap C C L C C L L L L L t L 252.32 moo— C C L L L L L L L L L .CE "33...; aa— C C C C C C C C C C C C C C L C C l mu: :2 L L L L L C L L L L ? L L L L L L 0:9 :2 C L L C C C L C ? L ? L L C L L L s .vcw @3— C L L L L L L L L L o L C L L L L L .m .um— @3— L L L L L L C C L L C L L L L L L L n”. 30> :2 L L L L C C C C C C L C C L C C L C L W .259 :a— C L L L L C C C C C C C C C C ? C C C C L 7 C Pu :3 no: L L L L L L L L uau map L L L L C C L C C C C l 32 noo— L C L L C L C ? C L L C .5... .53 "mm “mg. L C L L L C ? C L o. C L L L L L L .5... .03 .oom :3 ? C ? C C C ? C C ? C C. L C C C C 3.2.3 x2. :3 3 33:— .uom .8» mm: C L L L L L L C L C L L L C L L L L C .59: .uvm .UOm soo— L L L C C o C o L L L L C L L 35 9.on «3— C C L L L L C L L L L C L L C L L a... m .xuuzm a “no .vcoom moo— L ? C C C C C C C C C L C uau was. C C C C C C L L o C C L C L C C L L L L mum. .39 30—09 mm: L L C C C C C C C C C C C C C kw... .59 30— L L C C C L C C L C L C C L C r s .m a r. r. m m. a d a w M. S M. n .U m S J l r {x V. e (\ H 1M. M. M W 5 S 1l. mummmmmmmmummwmmnmmmmmmmmmmmmnmmmmm l l u t h 0 o P 0 O 0 e u o r .1 a EHNS&CHMSMCNBFRBHQchPAflkkfln—dmfifikkhpw 135 moon Com: aaxguuo: whoxuouo: .ecue< mxgo: .oaa "cu: ._.n .nsu case» .mnuou .mcou z.:o» .posovoz uoL< upguo—ona< .cs "3.2.5: In 3:. uzu s .vcm .n .... O H 3..» c H 4:8 .0 W S E uau l 33 .E*a .cguu ”mm .5...— .uom .uom 3:... 5 =8 3 .Luc_ .uom .uom .35 .uom .uom muau ecoam pip-58 .x.L=m a .39 .ocanm .3 .5. o....o .8 9 m Spend asap sno— soap moa— moa— nam— moo— asap ~55. ssmp asap ana— psa— psa— moo— mwa— nau— usu— sno— mom— swa— flflwwa. woo— Nsm— wom— som— C ? L L L L L L L C C L L L L L L L L L L C C L C Brooke Case L L L L L ? L C L C C C L ? L L L L L L L L L C L L L C C C Sparkman Johnston (S.C.) C L L L L L C L L L L L L L Johnston (La.) Long (La.) C L C C L C L L L L L L ? L L L C L ? ? L L L L L Fulbright Smathers Frear O'Mahoney Hi:key Ford LLL LLL L L L L L ? L L L L Huddleston Bumpers L L C L L L L Gore Moynihan Edmondson Kerr C C L L L L L L L L C L L L L L L ? Monroney L L L L L L L L L L C C L L R. Byrd (w.Va.) Cannon Bible L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C L L L L L C L L L Anderson (N.Mex.) Chavez L L Hayden L L C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C C L Randolph Montoya L L L L L L L L C C Johnson Sasser Bass L L L L L L L L L L C C L C Symington L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Long (Mo.) L C L L Mansfield Metcalf L L L L Hurray 14365 moon Low: maszuo: mauygouu: .ucmse ...o: .n:. Home __.n .as. e.=o» .mugou .mcou guao> .—u>ovo¢ uoL< ..gu...aa< .—uc_ "xaxlzsx an: nuns uau s .u=~ .n da— nm 3n» .n m .28 .m .... uau II: puu< .s.. .=L.. "mm .:.m .uow .uOm ....;m x.. cum av do... .uom .8» .Lu:_ .uom .uom nuau venom —.Lcue .xusam a .su .ucoam - uau n..m .3 338 a m c. use asu— num— soap nom— nom— noo— moo— ano— sump unm— oump osm— psa— —~m— mam— moo— noo— sna— smo— aca— snap _waa_ moo— wuo— wom— soo— L L L L L L C Eagleton L L L L C L L Gravel Harris L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C C L L Church Melcher Durkin L L L ? ? C L L L C L L L L L L L L L L L L L C L L C C McIntyre Biden Leahy Dodd ? L L L L L L L ? L C L L L L L L L L L L L C L C C C C C C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L ? Hartke L L L L C C C C L L L L L Proxmire Burdick Haskell L Riegle Anderson (Minn.) L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C Magnuson L L L L Jackson McGee L L L L L L L L L L L C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C Inouye L ,0 L L L L L L ) m a 39 H:— (n U 95 W?» L» L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C Hilliams (N.J.) Moss L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L ? L L L 7 L C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Bayh Pell L L L L L C C L L C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C L L Pastore L L L L C L L L Ribicoff J. Kennedy (Mass.) Glenn L L L L ? L L L L Stevenson LLL LLL LLL LLL LLL LLL LLL LLL LLL LLL ) .L S .l A ( 9?. ht. .al "he 69.5 m... .b R.“M ? L L C L Hart (Colo ) 1137 wood Lon: >o3g~uo$ nauseouo: .ecos< mxcoz .asa "cue p..m .nEu gaso> .mnsou .ucou guao> .—o>ocu¢ oog< ovguoponn< . CS SizS: in. amen usu .u:~ .um— ouo> .vcou ——,a .:u run puu< .19a .cgou "mm .c—u .uom .uOm 3:5 .3. =8 3 £2: .uom .uom .85 do. .8... ..=u ecoam ..L=ou . xubam a .3 65am .3 .3 328 .3 Public Horks Spend' m asap snap swo— meo— nom— nom— moo— asap sua— ska— asap osm— psa— psa— moo— moo— noo— una— sum— moo— sea— We: mom— Nua— moo— swo— L C L L L L ? L L L L L L L L L L L L L L ? L L C C C L L McGovern Abourezk L L L L L L Cranston Hughes L L L McCarthy Green Brewster Engle L L L L L L L Heuberger Carroll L L L Young (0.) Tunney L Smith (Mass.) Huskie L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L ? ? L L L L L C C L L L L Hathaway ? L R. Kennedy (N.Y.) Metzenbaum McNamara L L Humphrey Mondale Tydings ? L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C L L L L L L C C L L L E. Kennedy (Mass.) L L L L L Nelson L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Sarbanes Kefauver L L L Yarborough Clark (1a.) Culver L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Hart (Mich.) Douglas L L L L L L L L Clark (Pa.) 138 Minimun Rage Food Stams Unanp. Comp Bargaining Coll. .a .Luc_ .mmas .u=_ .vou .2: >18 ounuo>ou II .uga: .Lu_x .mcou .c.: co.mmouo¢ Unemp; Comp Bargaining Coll. ..v=..m .eou .L...L.m so» malnum took (ad: u:....u.a ouwm-coesou .Lo3-o.-.=o_x g.._o.< .oog ..~.m m.uxou .ueouom a $0 a .550: ...¢ .o ___m sap Nua— osm— cho— oom— usa— _ vuo. — Num— oom— «um— asap msa— moop amo— amm— amm— amm— C C C C C C C C C + + + L c Ellender Hill C + + + L c C c c CCCC CCCC Nunn Stone Bentsen Chiles C L L L L ? C C Hollings Morgan L Spong DeConcini Cook C C L C C L L Packwood C C L C L C L L C L L 80995 L C L C L L L C L L L C Fong Beall Sr. Beall Jr. Taft Saxbe C C C C L L C C C L L L C C L L L L L + L L L L L L L C L + L L Kuchel L C Cooper Smith (Me.) Prouty Aiken L L L L L L L L C L L C L + L C Chafee L Scott (Pa.) c L c c c L L L L L L L Heicker Percy ? C C L L L L C L L L L Hatfield Keating Stafford L C L L L C Schweiker Heinz L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Mathias L L L L L L L L L + + + L L Javits Goodell 141 Food Stamps Minimum Hage Unemp. Comp Bargaining Coll. as: 22 unm< mucusus_:ao¢ . 5.5.. stowox 1‘ .Lu:_ ri. .mcom .Lu:_ leis... 52; .Loc_ .mmog .u:_ .voc .oe_ za—yo ou-Losou ..L.: .Lo.z .mcon .c—l covmmouoa r .35.. £8 .to....m La. mas... sea. .1. (can ac..u.u.a 3.9.858”. {3-8-233 5:2: .ooa o.-.m «union .vcouom a .o a .88.. ...¢ .o ___c Tl sm— usa— onu— osm— oom— sum— _ vam— — wsm— ocu— cua— asa— mum— mam— amo— amm— ama— ama— L L C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C C C C C C C C L L Brooke Case L C L L L L L C L C L C L C L C C + + + L C Sparkman + + + L Johnston (S.C.) Johnston (La.) Long (La.) C C C C L C L L L C L L L C L L ? C L + + + L L C ? L L L C C C C Fulbright Smathers Frear C O'Mahoney Hickey L LLL LLL LLC L L LLC LCC n 0 L SS er le ddp rdm 0U FHB ? C L L L + + + C C L C C Gore Moynihan EdnondSOn Kerr L L L L L L L L L L L Monroney C C L L L L C L L C L L C + + + L C R. Byrd (H.Va.) Cannon Bible C C C C L L L C C C L C L L L L C L C C C C L L L L L L L +++LC C + + + L C L ? L L 7 L L L + + + L L Anderson (N Mex.) Chavez L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L ? + + + L C Hayden C L L L L L L L L RBDUOlPh + + + L L L Montoya Johnson L L L L L L + + + L fisur Bass L L C L L L L C L L L L L L L + + + L L Symington L L L L L L L L L L L Long (Mo.) Mansfield Metcalf L L L L L L L L L L + + + L L C L L L L L L L L L L + + + L Murray 1132 Food Stampsg Minimun Hage Unempi Comp Bargaining Coll. .aou .ng3 .La.: .mcou .=.: co..mouo¢ 633m .5 .L...L.m 5°C masoum woos w. ¢¢.= a:..u...a 0...-eosea. .Loz-o.-.go.¢ g.._oa< .oog o...m auuaoa .ucouom a so a .couou ...¢ .o p... 1" sap “so. a... a... a... “so. fiWWb. om. N... a... HUM... mm. a... com. com— onu— vam— muo— mso— mom— amm— amm— mmap ama— L L L L L ? L L L L L L Eagleton Gravel 9 Harris L L L L L C L L L L C L L ? L L L L C C C L L L C L L + + + L L Church Melcher Durkin L L L L L L C L L C L L L L L L McIntyre Biden Leahy Dodd L L L L L L L L L + L L + + + L L L L L a L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L ? ? Hartke C C C L L L L L L L L L L L L L + + + L L Proxmire Burdick L L L L L L L L L L LLL L LLL L L LLL L ) m n .sl M ( n «I. O glues Cl? Luge sed 6.1." HRA C C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L ? L L L L + + + L L Magnuson Jackson McGee L L C L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L + + + L L L L L L L + + + L L L ? L L L L L L L L L L Inouye Long (Haw.) Matsunaga L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C L L + + + L L Hilliams (N.J.) Moss L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C L L L L L ? L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L C L L L L L L + + + L L L L L L L L Bayh L L L L L L L L L Pell L L L + + + L L Pastore L L L L L Ribicoff J. Kennedy (Mass.) + + + L Glenn Stevenson L L L + + + L L Gruening + + Bartlett (Alsk.) Morse + + + L L Hart (Colo.) 1113 Food Stamggfl rl 1aou f .usaa .50.: .weom .c.t co—anuuoz 633m 68 ngox.Lum LoC unsnum room a: («.2 oe....u.a «fin-Eu .Lo:-o.-.;a_¢ gov—oa< .aog ....m nausea .vcouom a Co a .couox .muz Lo ——_o Tl sop «so. eso— oka— aco— sump osm— wo— Nao— com— com— oa— cho— awa— camp coo— vuap onu— msg— mam— omap amm— onw— ama— L C L L L L L L L L L L L C L L L McGovern Abourezk L L L L L ? L Cranston Hughes L + + + L L L L L L L L L L McCarthy Green L Brewster Engle + + + L L + + + L L Neuberger Carroll + + + L L L L L L L L L L + + + L L Young (0.) L L i. i. L & 5 mm v. e .h n _t n .l .m .w L L L L L ? L L L L L L L L L ? L L L + + + L L Muskie Hathaway L R. Kennedy (N.Y.) Metzenbaum McNamara + + + L L + + + L L Humphrey L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Mondale Tydings C ? L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L L Nelson L L L L L E. Kennedy (Mass.) Sarbanes Kefauver 4. Yarborough Clark(Ia.) Culver L L L L L L L L L L L L L + + + L L Hart (Mich.) Douglas + + + L L L L L L L L + + + L L Clark (Pa.) 144 Survey of the Voting Records .lgtroduction The votes, and the alignment patterns they produced, may now be examined, grouped according to issue area. When a number of votes in a given area are similar enough in their substance and in the alignments of those voting for them, then they will be considered collectively. Senators will be separated into those who were always on the one side of the issue (when they voted), those who were always on the other side (when they voted) and those who were some- times on the one side and sometimes on the other. This will mean different things in the case of different votes. For example, on spending issues, Senators may be identified as consistent supporters of high or of low spending, or as those with mixed voting records. Votes on other kinds of issues would be described analogously. (Later, after these voting alignments have been surveyed, "conservative" and "liberal” sides will be identified for most of them. Consequently, in the case of most issue areas, the Senators will be divided into consistent conservatives, consistent liberals, and moderates.) In the case of each issue area examined, the Senators will be considered as members of the groups discussed earlier (conserva- tive and liberal Republicans, conservative Northern, 01d Southern, New Southern and liberal Democrats). When, as usually happens, a clear majority of a group is on a given side of a set of issues, it will be simply noted that most of them are on that side. Only the 145 minority, the deviants, will be named individually. In some cases, an individual has not taken stands on enough of the votes in a set to state firmly where he belongs, yet there may be reason to believe, on the basis of those votes on which he has taken a position (and sometimes on the basis of his votes on other issues, and other facts), that he can be placed on one side or another. We may note these as "perhaps" belonging to a given side. The following abbreviations will be used below: CR (Conser- vative Republican), CND (Conservative Northern Democrat), OSD (Old South Democrat), NSD (New South Democrat), LR (Liberal Republican), and LD (Liberal Democrat). The votes that were finally selected fell in the following areas: income taxes; tariffs; general spending; revenue sharing; public works (including public works jobs, Area Redevelopment, aid to Applachia and youth employment, among other issues); water projects; social security; labor issues (including unemployment compensation, union legislation, minimum wages and food stamps for strikers); food stamps; Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC); the Office of Economic Opportunity (0E0), legal services, child care, the School Lunch Program, Youth Training and the Nat- ional Service Corps; housing (including rent subsidies, Demonstration Cities, etc.); education aid; health (including Medicare, etc.); general appropriations for the Departments of Labor and HEW; collec- tive bargaining on railroads; aid to local mass transit; the Super- sonic Transport (SST), Lockheed and the Communications Satellite 146 company; wage and price controls; fuel rationing and the Federal Energy Administration (PEA); no-fault insurance; antitrust law, air- line deregulation; consumer protection; the National Consumer Cooperative Bank; the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA); and environmental protection (including pollution, strip- mining and Alaska pipeline); and nuclear energy. Income Taxes 147 The first issue area to consider is that of income taxes. The first vote in this area is that on the 1962 tax bill, which cut various income taxes, including some business taxes. FOR most LDs most OSDs most LRs CRs Mundt, Jordan (Ida.), Cotton, Allott, Capehart, Dirksen, Wiley, Carlson and Martin CND Lausche The 1964 income tax bill tax cut. FOR most LDs most LRs OSDs Holland, Robertson, Jordan (N.C.), Eastland and Talmadge AGAINST most CRs CND Lausche OSDs Stennis and Russell LRs Saltonstall and Keating LDs Hart (Mich.), Douglas, Clark (Pa.) Neuberger, Gore, Yarborough, MacNamara, Morse, Bartlett (Alsk.) Gruening and Burdick was a general personal and corporate AGAINST most CRs CND Lausche OSDs Harry Byrd Sr., Ervin, Russell, Stennis and McClellan LRs Aiken LDs Ellender, Proxmire and Neuberger In 1968 a bill was passed providing for a spending cut coupled with a surtax. FOR most LDs LR Hatfield OSD Talmadge CRs Cotton and Young (N.Dak.) In 1969, an amendment to ing the surtax for one-half year. AGAINST most CRs most OSDs CND Lausche most LRs LDs Sparkman and Gore another bill was proposed extend- FOR most LDs LRs Javits, Case, Aiken and Hatfield most OSDs 148 AGAINST most CR3 most LRs LDs Robert Byrd (W. Va.), Cannon, Bible, Williams (N.J.), Young (0.) and Nelson Later in 1969, an income tax bill was passed which increased personal taxation of the wealthy, decreased that of most other groups, and increased the tax liability of businesses. It also provided an increase in social security benefits of 15% with an increase in social security taxes. FOR unst LDs most LRs most OSDs CRs Young (N.Dak.) and Baker AGAINST most CRs OSDs Russell and Holland LRs Smith (Me.), Saxbe, Percy and Brooke Another vote concerning this bill was on an amendment to increase the exemption. FOR most LDs LRs Cook, Fong, Aiken, Prouty and Hatfield CRs Young (N.Dak.) and Baker AGAINST most CRs most LRs OSDs Russell, Holland and Harry Byrd Jr. A.vote from 1971 was on reducing the depreciation allowance. FOR most LDs LR Case OSD Stennis AGAINST most CRs most OSDs most LRs LDs Pastore and Ribicoff Another vote on the same bill is on an amendment equalizing the tax rate for single and married persons. 149 FOR AGAINST CRs Allott, Young (N.Dak)., most CRs Griffin, Dole and Baker most OSDs OSD McClellan LRs Bellman, Cook, Boggs, Beall, LRs Pearson, Stevens, Packwood, Taft, Saxbe, Smith (Me.), Prouty, Fong, Weicker, Hatfield, Aiken, Scott (Pa.), Percy, Mathias, Schweiker and Brooke Javits and Case (N.J.) NSD Chiles NSDs Bentsen, Hollings and Spong LDs Ellender, Sparkman, Long most LDs (La.), Fulbright, Byrd (W.Va.), Cannon, Bible, Anderson (N.Mex), Randolph, Montoya, Mansfield, Church, Williams (N.J.), Percy, Young (0) and E. Kennedy (Mass.) The 1975 tax bill cut personal and corporate taxes. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CRs most LRs most OSDs most NSDs LRs Bellman, Pearson and Hatfield CRs Buckley, Brock, Dole, LD Mansfield Domenici and Roth The first 1976 tax vote was on killing a motion to recommit the tax bill of that year to committee, with instructions to report it back with only the personal tax benefits still in it. To oppose the motion was to vote in favor of making the bill consist of personal tax relief only. FOR HAVING PERSONAL RELIEF ONLY AGAINST HAVING PERSONAL RELIEF ONLY most LDs most CRs most NSDs most OSDs LRs Scott (Pa.), Weicker, most LRs Mathias, Brooke and Javits LDs Byrd (W. Va.), Cannon, Bible, CRs Tower, Laxalt, Garn, Randolph, Johnston (La.), Long Helms, McClure, Domenici and (La.), Sparkman, Matsunaga, Inouye, Baker Jackson, Magnuson, McGee, Ribicoff, Pastore, Cranston and Burdick 150 Another tax vote was one from 1976 on tax credits for cor- porations for taxes paid to foreign governments. The vote was on reconsidering an amendment to reduce the effective benefits to the companies. FOR most LDs NSDs Nunn, Chiles, Hollings, Huddleston and Bumpers LRs Schweiker, Brooke and Case (N.J.) AGAINST most CRs most OSDs most LRs NSDs Bentsen, Stone, Morgan, Johnston (La.) and Ford LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Randolph, Gravel, Biden, McGee, Inouye, Williams (N.J.) and Pell The 1977 tax vote was on an amendment which would have made a permanent tax cut for people with incomes under $20,000. FOR most CRs CND Zorinsky most LRs LDs Biden, McIntyre, Durkin, Riegle and Proxmire AGAINST most LDs most NSDs most OSDs CRs Scott (Va.) and Young (N.D.) LR Hatfield Next, we have a 1978 tax cut vote on an amendment which would have made a permanent tax cut for people with incomes under $50,000. FOR most LDs NSDs Ford, Huddleston, and Bumpers LRs Percy, Packwood, Schweiker, Brooke and Case (N.J.) CRs Helms, Thurmond, McClure, Domenici, Dole and Griffin AGAINST most CRs most OSDs LRs Packwood, Chafee, Weicker, Mathias, and Javits NSDs Nunn, Bentsen, Chiles, Hollings, Johnston (La.) and Morgan 151 Another vote on the 1978 tax bill was on the Kemp-Roth amendment, which provided for a 30% across-the-board personal tax cut over a three-year period (beginning in 1979). AGAINST FOR most LDs most CRs most LRs NSD Nunn and Johnston (La.) most NSDs LRs Bellman, Stevens, Schweiker, most OSDs Packwood, Chafee, Percy and Heinz LDs Proxmire, Sparkman, and Gravel Still another vote on the 1978 bill was an amendment to cut the corporate tax rate from 48% to 44%. AGAINST NSDs Nunn, Stone, Chiles, most LDs Bentsen, Ford and Johnston (La.) NSDs Huddleston and Bumpers most LRS OSDs Stennis, Eastland and LDS DEConcini, Cannon, Moynihan, Talmadge Sparkman, Proxmire, Sasser, Biden, Durkin, Leahy, Riegle, Anderson FOR (Minn.), Gravel, Hart (Colo.), mOSt CR3 Eagleton, Ribicoff, Williams and OSD H. Byrd Jr. Inouye CND Zorinsky Tariff Issues Another issue area is related to tariff protection, or at least to executive discretion in lowering tariffs. One of the votes was on a proposed amendment to the Trade Expansion Act of 1962, to preserve the requirement that the President inform Congress if he cuts tariffs below a "peril point" determined by the Tariffs Com— mission. FOR PRESIDENTIAL POWER AGAINST PRESIDENTIAL POWER most LDs most CRs OSDs Holland and Jordan (N.C.) most OSDs most LRs LDs Cannon, Bible, Church and Dodd 152 The other vote was a 1974 vote involving cloture on a bill to allow the President to negotiate trade agreements on lower trade barriers. FOR CLOTURE ON PRESIDENTIAL AGAINST CLOTURE ON PRESIDENTIAL POWER POWER OSDs Stennis, Eastland, mast CR3 McClellan, Allen and Ervin most NSDs Nunn and Hollings CR3 Gurney and McClure mast LRs LRs Schweiker and Case (N.J.) OSDs Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.) and NSDs Chiles Talmadge LDs Bible, Cannon, Metcalf, Hartke, Bayh, Abourezk, Muskie, Hart (Mich.) and Proxmire General Spending We have several votes on this topic from the late 19603 and early 19703 and another from 1978. Considering the former votes first, we see that there is one on a spending cut in 1967, another on a spending cut coupled with the imposition of a temporary surtax in 1968 (see above), another on an amendment to this last proposal that would remove the spending cut provision from it, and one on giving the president power to cut the budget in certain areas, from 1972. We may consider separately the proposal from 1968 which coupled the spending cut with a surtax. Considering the other three (from 1967, 1968 and 1972) together, we can see that the following alignment exists. AGAINST ALL THREE CUTS HAVING A MIXED RECORD most LDs CRs Jordan (Ida.) and Griffin NSDs Hollings and Spong OSDs McClellan, Holland, Ervin, LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Jordan (N.C.) and Talmadge Fulbright, Gore, Byrd (W.Va.), LRs Fong, Smith (Me.),Aiken, 153 AGAINST ALL THREE CUTS HAVING A MIXED RECORD Cannon, Bible, Anderson(N} MexJ.‘Hatfield, Javits, Brooke and Case Randolph, Montoya, Symington, (N.J.) and perhaps Weicker, Stafford, Mansfield, Church, McIntyre, Schweiker and Mathias Hartke, Pastore, Ribicoff, McGovern, McCarthy and Nelson FOR ALL THREE CUTS most CRs OSDs Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.), Stennis, Eastland (and perhaps Russell and Allen) perhaps CND Lausche LRs Boggs, Cooper, Scott (Pa.) and Percy (and perhaps Bellman, Pearson, Kuchel and Prouty) LD Proxmire The 1968 proposal for a spending cut coupled with a surtax was already discussed above under taxes, but we shall repeat the findings. AGAINST FOR most LDs most CR3 LR Hatfield most OSDs OSD Talmadge CND Lausche CR3 Cotton and Young (N.Dak.) most LRs LD Sparkman and Gore The remaining vote on general spending is from 1978, and is an amendment to a budget bill. AGAINST FOR CR Goldwater. Laxalt. Tower. CR3 Curtis, Helms, Scott (Va.), Bartlett. Hansen. Young (N.Dak-) Thurmond, Hatch, McClure, Lugar and and Dale Roth OSDs Eastland, Stennis, and CND Zorinsky Talmadge OSD Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.) and Allen mast LRs LRs Hatfield and Heinz NSDs Bentsen, Chiles, Hollings, NSDs Nunn, Stone, Ford and Huddleston Morgan, Johnston (La.) and LDs DeConcini, Sasser, Durkin, Bumpers McIntyre, Biden, Leahy, Proxmire, most LDs Haskell, Hart (Colo.), McGovern, Church, Nelson and Metzenbaum Revenue Sharing 154 In this area are several votes on the 1972 bill establishing revenue sharing. One was a proposed amendment setting the amount of revenue shared at $8,100,000.000 in the first two years and requiring annual congressional approval of it in fiscal years 1974-77. FOR CRs Dominick, Hruska, Gurney, Cotten, Allott, Young (N.Dak.) and Roth OSDs Stennis, Eastland, Ervin, Jordan (N.C.), McClellan and Allen LRs Pearson, Stevens, Boggs, Fang, Brooke and Case (N.J.) LDs Byrd (W.Va.), Bible, Symington, Mansfield, Metcalf, Gravel, Burdick, Magnuson, Jackson, McGee, Inouye, Williams (N.J.), Bayh, Pell, Pastore and Ribicoff AGAINST CR3 Thurmond, Tower, Buckley, Curtis, Bennett, Fannin, Jordan (Ida.), Miller, Hansen, Brock, Griffin, Dale and Baker OSDs Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.) and Talmadge most LRs LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Fulbright, Cannon, Anderson (N.Mex.), Randolph, Montoya, McIntyre, Hartke, Proxmire, Riegle, Moss, Stevenson, McGovern, Cranston, Hughes, Muskie, Humphrey, Mondale, Tunney, E. Kennedy (Mass.) and Hart (Mich.) Another vote was an amendment regarding the distribution of aid. The amendment proposed an increase in the share going to populous, urbanized states. FOR LDs Bible, Gravel, Williams (N.J.), Ribicoff, Inouye, Bayh, Pastore, Hartke, Stevenson, Cranston, Tunney, E. Kennedy (Mass.) and Hart (Mich.) LRs Stevens, Boggs, Fang, Saxbe, Scott (Pa.), Weicker, Javits, Brooke and Case (N.J.) CRs Buckley and Roth AGAINST most CR3 most OSDs mast NSDs LRs Bellman, Pearson, Cook, Packwood, Cooper, Smith (Me.), Beall Jr., Percy, Hatfield and Mathias LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Byrd (W. Va.), Cannon, Anderson (N.Mex.), Montoya, Randolph, Fulbright, Proxmire, Eagleton, Symington, Mansfield, Metcalf, Burdick, Church, Moss, Jackson, Magnuson, Hughes, Muskie, Humphrey, Mondale and Nelson 155 The last vote was on passage of the bill. FOR AGAINST most CRs CR3 Goldwater, Curtis, Jordan (Id.) OSDs Allen, Eastland, and Young (N.D.) McClellan, Talmadge and OSDs Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.), Stennis Jordan (N.C.) and Ervin most LRs LRs Taft, Saxbe, Percy and Hatfield NSDs Spong and Hollings NSDs Bentsen and Chiles most LDs LDs Byrd (W.Va.), Bible, Symington, Mansfield, Eagleton, Proxmire, Burdick, Church, Stevenson, Metzenbaum and Nelson A related vote concerned the Humphrey-Hawkins bill of 1978, an economic stimulus program which included a public works jobs measure. The vote was on an amendment to the bill to modify a pro- vision setting a goal of 3% inflation in 1983 and 0% inflation in 1988. The amendment would delete the 0% inflation goal and the time limit for the 3% goal. FOR DELETION AGAINST DELETION most LDs most CR3 LRs Brooke, Case (N.J.) and mast OSDs Heinz most LRs OSD Talmadge NSDs Nunn, Bentsen, Stone, Chiles NSDs Ford, Huddleston, Bumpers, and Holland Morgan and Johnston (La.) LDs Eagleton, Ribicoff, Proxmire, CR Danforth Hart (Colo.), McGovern and Nelson Public Works The next area is that of public works. There are several sub-areas within it. They are; (1) public works whose main purpose is to provide public works jobs; (2) public works which aim not only to provide jobs but also to assist in economic development; (3) those projects whose main purpose is to provide regional economic 156 development, rather than directly providing jobs; and (4) public works of the traditional sort, which serve other functions commonly performed by government (e.g. the construction of roads, canals and sewers). area, that of youth employment. Also included with this heading will be a fifth sub- The first sub-area in the area of public works is that of public works jobs projects. It is represented by two votes from 1976 and one from 1977 on public works jobs programs, and one from 1977 on an economic stimulus package that included the public works jobs program of that year. and then the last. CONSISTENTLY ON HIGH- SPENDING SIDE most LDs LRs Javits, Case, Brooke, Mathias, Stafford, Hatfield and Weicker (and perhaps Heinz, Taft and Beall Jr.) NSDs Stone, Bentsen, Ford and Huddleston OSD Talmadge CONSISTENTLY ON LOW- SPENDING SIDE most CR3 OSDs Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.) and McClellan LD Proxmire AGAINST most CRs OSD Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.) LD Proxmire We will first consider the first three, HAVING A MIXED RECORD CRs Buckley, Brock, Roth and Baker OSDs Eastland, Stennis and Allen LRs Bellman, Pearson, Stevens, Packwood, Fang, Schweiker and Percy (and probably Scott of Pa.) NSDs Nunn, Chiles, Hollings, Morgan, Johnson (La.) and Bumpers LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Byrd (W.Va.), Gravel, Biden, and Hathaway probably CND Zorinsky FOR most LDs most LRs most NDs most OSDs CRS Thurmond, Schmitt, Lugar, Danforth, Griffin, Domenici and Baker CND Zorinsky 157 The second sub-area of public works is that of public works intended to provide economic development as well as jobs. Included under this heading are a vote on cutting spending for an accelerated public works program in 1963, a vote on passage of a 1965 bill, a vote on an amendment to that bill reducing its spending level, and two votes on passing a 1971 bill--a vote on the conference version and the one an overriding the veto. (These are distinguished from the more explicitly regional economic development votes, on the Appalachia and Area Redevelopment bills—~see below). CONSISTENTLY ON HIGH-SPENDING HAVING A MIXED RECORD SIDE CRs Fannin, Bennett, Murphy, Gurney, most LDs Cotton, Dirksen, and Carlson OSDs Eastland, Stennis, Ervin, OSDs Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.), McClellan and Jordan (N.C.) (and pro- and Talmadge (and perhaps Harry bably Allen Byrd Sr. [Va.], Robertson and LR Case (N.J.) (and perhaps Holland) Schweiker) mast LRs LDs Ellender and Proxmire CONSISTENTLY ON LOW-SPENDING probably CND Lausche SIDE most CR3 The sub-area of regional economic development contains two votes: the one on the Area Redevelopment Bill of 1963 and one on the Appalachian Development bill of 1965. The only one voted against the Appalachian bill but for the Area Redevelopment bill was liberal Democrat Proxmire. Otherwise, the two votes form a perfect scale, as shown below. FOR most LDs most LRs OSDs Ervin, Jordan (N.C.), Talmadge and Holland AGAINST most CR3 OSDs Harry Byrd Sr. (Va.) Robertson, Stennis, Eastland and McClellan LRs Pearson and Boggs LD Ellender 158 IN FAVOR OF APPALACHIAN BUT OPPOSED TO AREA REDEVELOPMENT CR3 Bennett and Dirksen CND Lausche OSD Russell LR Kuchel (and perhaps Beall Sr.) The fourth kind of public works project is public works so-called, as opposed to public works jobs. list by this precise name. projects which fit this description. here. We have none on our However, there are some votes on water There are two votes involved The first (1977) is on a substitute amendment to build a dam and locks in Illinois and have user fees studied. FOR CR3 Scott (Va.), Thurmond, Tower, Laxalt, Garn, Hatch, Hansen, Young (N.Dak.), Roth and Danforth OSDs Stennis, Eastland, McClellan and Allen LRs Stevens, Packwood, Percy, Hatfield, Schweiker and Heinz NSDs Hollings, Johnston (La.), Ford, Huddleston and Bumpers LDs DeConcini, Sparkman, Lang (La.), Moynihan, Eagleton, Burdick, Magnuson, Jackson, Williams (N.J.), Ribicoff, Glenn, Stevenson, Cranston.. Tunney and Humphrey AGAINST CR3 Goldwater, Helms, Curtis, McClure, Lugar, Hayakawa, Schmitt, Domenici, Wallop, Griffin, Dale and Baker CN Zorinsky OSDs Harry Byrd Jr. Talmadge LRs Bellman, Chafee, weicker, Stafford, Mathias, Javits, Brooke and Case (N.J.) NSDs Nunn, Bentsen, Chiles and Morgan LDs Byrd (W.Va.), Pell, Hart (Colo.), Cannon, Randolph, Gravel, McIntyre, Biden, Proxmire, McGovern, Cranston, Muskie, Hathaway, Metzen— baum, Nelson, E. Kennedy (Mass.), Clark (1a.) and Culver (Va.) and 159 The second vote relating to waterways was on an amendment to authorize collection of user fees for them (1978). AGAINST FOR CR3 Scott, Thurmond, Tower, CRs Goldwater, Curtis, McClure, Laxalt, Garn, Hatch, Bartlett Lugar, Hayakawa, Schmitt, Domenici, (Okla.), Hansen, Young (N.Daka), and Wallop Roth, Dole, Baker and Danforth CND Zorinsky LRs Stevens, Packwood, Weicker, OSDs H. Byrd Jr. (Va.) and Talmadge Hatfield, Schweiker and Heinz LRs Bellman, Chafee, Stafford, Percy, OSDs Stennis and Eastland Mathias, Javits, Brooke and Case (N.J.) NSDs Bentsen, Hollings, NSDs Nunn and Chiles Johnston (La.), Ford, LDs Randolph, Melcher, McIntyre, Huddleston and Bumpers Biden, Proxmire, Williams LDs DeConcini, Sparkman, (N.J.), Bayh, Ribicoff, Glenn, Long (La.), Moynihan, Byrd Stevenson, Cranston, Muskie, (W.Va.), Eagleton, Gravel, Hathaway, Metzenbaum, Nelson, Burdick, Magnuson, Jackson, E. Kennedy (Mass.), Clark (1a.) Pell and McGovern and Culver Related to these public works votes are two on the Youth Employment bill of 1963. One is on the passage of it, the other is an amendment to remove the portion of the bill which provided for a Youth Conservation Corps (YCC). The only one opposed to the amendment who opposed passage of the bill was Old South Democrat Holland. Otherwise, the two votes scale perfectly. FOR YCC AND BILL AGAINST YCC BUT IN FAVOR OF BILL most LDs LRs Smith (Me.), Scott (Pa.), LRs Fang, Cooper and Case Kuchel, Keating and Javits (N.J.) AGAINST YCC AND BILL most CR3 most OSDs CND Lausche most LRs LDs Monroney, Fulbright, Sparkman, Hill and Ellender 160 Social Security These votes include some on general increases in benefits, another on changing the tax formula, and another on the outside earnings limitation. In the first category are a vote on a substitute proposal for a benefit increase (12.5% instead of 15%), with a tax increase, and a vote on the passage of the 1969 income tax bill, which included a 15% increase in social security benefits, with a tax increase. ON THE HIGH-SPENDING SIDE HAVING A MIXED RECORD OF BOTH (High-Spending in 1967 but Low- Spending in 1969) most LDs LRs Prouty, Aiken, Scott CR3 Cotton and Griffin (Pa.), Hatfield, Javits OSD Russell and Case(N.J.) (and perhaps LR Smith (Me.) Packwood, Cook, Fang, perhaps CND Lausche Schweiker and Mathias) NSD Hollings (Low-Spending in 1967, but High- OSD Ervin (and probably Spending in 1969) Jordan of N.C. and Talmadge) CR‘ Young (N.Dak.) OSDs Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.), Stennis, Eastland and McClellan ON THE LOW-SPENDING SIDE OF BOTH CR3 Dominick, Miller and Baker LR Boggs most CRs NSD Spong OSD Holland LD Ellender LRs Pearson and Percy Another social security vote, from 1977, involved the ques- tions of whether the wage base for employers should be raised to the same or to a greater level than that to which it would be raised for employee, and how high the tax rate should be. A substitute amend- ment, providing for equal wage bases and a higher tax rate, was proposed, and a motion was made to kill it. 161 AGAINST SUBSTITUTE FOR SUBSTITUTE most LDs most CR3 LRs Stafford and Case (N.J.) most LRs NSD Morgan LDs Moynihan, Byrd (W.Va.), Randolph and Inouye Another vote on the same social security bill is on an amend- ment concerning outside earnings limitations. An amendment to ease the restrictions was proposed, but another (the one we are concerned with) was proposed as a substitute. The substitute would have moderated the original by raising the age at which its provisions would take effect. FOR SUBSTITUTE AGAINST SUBSTITUTE most LDs most CR3 most LRs and NSDs OSDs Stennis, Eastland and Talmadge CRs Curtis, Zorinsky and LRs Packwood and Percy Roth NSDs Stone LDs Randolph and Pell Labor Issues The next subject is that of labor issues. There are several sub-areas within it: unemployment compensation, food stamps for strikers, union (collective bargaining) legislation and minimumlwage laws. The sub-area of unemployment compensation involves three votes on a bill from 1966, one on a bill from 1970 and another on a bill from 1972. The 1966 bill provided for the setting of national minimum standards for the unemployment compensation systems in the various states. FOR BILL most LDs most LRs OSD Talmadge 162 AGAINST BILL most CR3 most OSDs CND Lausche LRs Saltonstall, Pearson and Cooper LDs Ellender, Hill, Sparkman and Smathers Another vote on this bill is one an amendment to provide full federal funding of extended unemployment compensation coverage in recessions. FOR most LDs LRs Javits, Case (N.J.), Aiken, Prouty and Smith (Me.) AGAINST most CR3 most OSDs CND Lausche LRs Pearson, Boggs, Fang, Cooper Kuchel and Scott (Pa.) LDs Cannon, Bible and Symington The third vote on this bill was on another amendment which set minimum levels in each state for maximum benefits at one-half the average statewide wage. FOR most LDs LRs Boggs, Prouty, Aiken, Javits and Case (N.J.) CR Miller AGAINST most CRs most OSDs CND Lausche LRs Pearson, Smith (Me.), Cooper, Kuchel and Scott (Pa.) LDs Cannon, Bible, Harris, Jackson and McGovern The next vote on unemployment compensation comes from 1970. It is an amendment providing for the inclusion of migrant workers in the program. 163 FOR AGAINST most LDs most CRs most LRs mast OSDs CRs Murphy, Griffin, Dole LRs Bellman, Packwood, Boggs, Fang, and Baker Smith (Me.), Scott (Pa.) and Mathias NSD Spong LDs Cannon, Bible, Long (La.) and Ellender The last unemployment compensation vote is from 1972. It is on an amendment extending coverage beyond the existing time limits. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 most LRs most OSDs NSD Chiles and Hollings LRs Smith (Me.), Cooper, Percy and CR3 Baker, Griffin and Brock Mathias OSD Talmadge NSD Spong and LD Sparkman The next sub-area of labor issues is that concerning the issues of food stamps for strikers. It contains one vote, from 1974. FOR AGAINST most LDs mast CR3 most LRs most OSDs NSD Huddleston most NSDs CR Young (N.Dak.) LRs Fang and Scott (Pa.) Another sub—area is that concerning unions (collective bar- gaining), which includes four votes on labor relations amendments to the Landrum—Griffin bill (1959); a bill to abolish right-tadwork laws (1965); a bill to allow common-site picketing (1975); and a bill changing union recognition procedure in a pro-union direction. The first vote is that on an amendment to the Landrum—Griffin bill allowing state regulation of labor disputes where no federal regula- tion applies. 164 The second vote on this bill is on an amendment establish- ing a set of restraints on unions to protect their members, called a "Bill of Rights". AGAINST FOR mast LDs most CR3 LR Javits mast OSDs CND Lausche most LRs LDs Fulbright, Smathers, Chavez and Dodd The third vote is on reconsidering the previous one. AGAINST FOR most LDs most CR3 LR Javits most OSDs CND Lausche LDs Fulbright, Smathers, Chavez and Dodd The fourth vote is on an amendment that, among other things, banned all secondary boycotts. AGAINST FOR LRs Kuchel, Cooper, Smith most CR3 (Me.), Aiken and Javits most OSDs CND Lausche LRs Saltonstall, Beall Sr., Scott (Pa.), Prouty, Keating and Case (N.J.) LDs Fulbright, Smathers, Kerr, Monroney and Bartlett FOR most LDs most LRs 165 AGAINST mast CR3 mast OSDs CND Lausche LR Saltonstall, Beall Sr. and Scott (Pa.) LDs Fulbright, Smathers, Kerr, Gore and Kefauver The next vote on collective bargaining is on a proposal to repeal the provision of the Taft-Hartley Act allowing right-to-work laws. FOR most LDs most LRs AGAINST most CR3 most OSDs CND Lausche LRs Saltonstall, Pearson, Boggs, Fang, Aiken and Prouty LDs Ellender, Hill, Sparkman, Fulbright, Smathers, Byrd (W.Va.), Gore, Monroney and Hayden The next collective bargaining vote is on the bill to allow common-site picketing (1975). FOR mast LRs most LDs NSD Ford AGAINST mast CR3 most OSDs most NSDs LRs Bellman, Pearson, Fang, Scott (Pa.) and Hatfield LDs Sparkman, Cannon, McIntyre, Glenn and Nelson The last collective bargaining vote is on a bill which would make it easier for unions to organize (1978). FOR most LDs mast LRs AGAINST most CRs most OSDs CND Zorinsky mast NSDs LR Bellman LDs Sparkman, Long (La.) and Cannon 166 The last sub—area of labor issues is that of minimum wage legislation. There are several votes in this area which may be grouped into a number of sets. From 1966 and 1974 are votes on the passage of minimum wage increases; from 1961 and 1966 are votes on the width of coverage of minimum wage laws; from 1966 is a vote on delaying an increase and from 1972 is a similar one on reducing the proposed increase; and from 1977 is one on providing a youth sub- minimum wage. There are two votes (from 1966 and 1974) on passage of bills to increase the minimum wage. The first we will consider is the one from 1966. FOR AGAINST most LDs mast CR3 most LRs most OSDs OSD Talmadge LDs Ellender and Fulbright CR3 Dominick, Mundt, Williams (Del.), Bennett, Murphy, Miller, Allott, Morton and Griffin. The second bill of this kind to consider is the one from 1974. FOR AGAINST most LDs mast CR3 most LRs most OSDs most NSDs LR Bellman CR3 Brock, Young (N.Dak.), NSD Hollings Domenici, Dale and Baker OSDs Allen and Talmadge These two bills may also be considered as a group. FOR BOTH most LDs most LRs OSD Talmadge probably CRs Domenici, Dale and Baker HAVING MIXED RECORD CR3 Bennett and Young (N.Dak.) (and probably Dominick, Mundt, Williams of Del., Murphy, Miller, Allott, Brock, Morton and Griffin probably CND Lausche OSD Ervin (and probably Jordan [N.C.] and Allen) LRs Pearson (and probably C00 and Taft) ' NSD Hollings (and perhaps most other NSDs) LD Fulbright 167 AGAINST BOTH mast CRs most OSDs LD Ellender Votes on the width of coverage come from 1961 and 1966. First we will consider the 1961 vote. FOR mast LDs most LRs AGAINST mast CR3 most OSDs LDs Hill, Sparkman and Fulbright (and perhaps Ellender and Smathers) The other vote on this subject was from 1966. FOR mast LDs most LRs AGAINST most CR3 most OSDs CND Lausche LRs Saltonstall, Pearson, COOper, Prouty and Aiken LDs Ellender, Hill, Sparkman, Fulbright, Smathers, Monroney, Cannon, Bible and McGovern 168 We may now consider the two votes on width of coverage together. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CRs most LRs mast OSDs CND Lausche HAVING A MIXED RECORD LR Saltonstall LD Ellender, Hill, Sparkman, CR Miller Fulbright, Smathers and Monroney LRs Pearson, Cooper, Prouty and Aiken (and perhaps Beall Sr.) LDs Cannon, Bible, Gore and McGovern Another kind of minimum wage vote is that on delaying a proposed increase. We have one of these votes on our list taken in 1966. AGAINST FOR most LDs most CR3 most LRs most OSDs CND Lausche LRs Saltonstall, Pearson, Boggs and Cooper LDs Ellender, Hill, Sparkman, Long (La.), Symington, Harris and Church Still another kind of minimum wage vote is that on reducing a proposed increase. We have one of these votes on our list taken in 1972. AGAINST FOR most LDs most CR3 most LRs most OSDs mast NSDs LRs Bellman, Pearson, Cook, Packwood, Fang, Beall Sr., Taft, Saxbe, Hatfield and Mathias LDs Ellender, Sparkman, Long (La.) and Mass 169 The proposal to delay the minimum wage increase in 1966 and the one to oppose it in 1972 are alike in that they involve the question of degree of increase, rather than that of whether there should be an increase at all, which is implied in the vote on passage. We may consider them now as a group. AGAINST DELAYING AND REDUCTION FOR DELAYING AND REDUCTION mast LDs mast LRs most LRs most OSDs most NSDs HAVING A MIXED RECORD LRs Pearson and Cooper (and perhaps Taft, Beall Jr., Cook and Packwood) LRs Boggs, Fang and Mathias LDs Hill, Sparkman and Fulbright LDs Long (La.), Randolph, (and perhaps Ellender and Smathers) Symington, McIntyre, Moss, Harris and Church The last minimum wage vote to be considered is that on the youth sub-minimum wage amendment of 1977, to permit the employing of workers under 20 at 85% of the minimum wage for the first six months on the job. AGAINST FOR most LDs most CRs most LRs most OSDs NSDs Bentsen, Johnston (La.), CND Zorinsky Ford and Huddleston LRs Stevens, Bellman, Chafee, Percy, Hatfield, and Schweiker NSDs Nunn, Stone, Chiles, Hollings, Morgan and Bumpers LDs Sparkman, Long (La.) and Cannon Several of these cleavages relating to labor issues can be put together in something approximating a scale. The votes on the scale, in approximate order from the least to the most "pro-labor" or "pro-union", are: the minimum wage increases of 1966 and 1974 (considered together), the unemployment compensation act of 1966, 170 and the 1978 vote on making recognition easier for the unions. Scal- ing with all of these, except the last one, are the amendments to delay (1966) or reduce (1972) proposed minimum wage increases (con- sidered together). (Many of the other votes are related to these. For example, the boundary between the consistent opponents of broad minimum-wage coverage and those with mixed records on the subjects seem to correspond closely to that between opponents and supporters of the 1966 unemployment compensation bill, while the boundary between the consistent supporters of broad minimum wage coverage and those with mixed records corresponds to the boundary between the supporters and opponents of the 1978 union bill.) Food Stamps We may now turn to the next major area of votes, which is that involving votes on food stamps (apart from those on strikers' food stamps, already dealt with above). The following votes are included in this category: an amendment to raise the increase in spending provided for in the food stamps bill of 1969; an amendment increasing food stamps funds in 1970; a bill to increase spending in 1976, and an amendment to eliminate the purchase requirement in 1977. ON HIGH-SPENDING SIDE OF 0N LOWrSPENDING SIDE OF ALL FOUR ALL FOUR most CR3 most LDs most OSDs most LRs mast OSDs 171 HAVING A MIXED RECORD CRS Dole, Baker, Lugar and Danforth CND Zorinsky OSD Talmadge NSDs Nunn, Bentsen, Johnston (La.) and Morgan LRs Boggs, Fang, Packwood, Stevens and Schweiker (and probably Aiken and Smith (Me.) LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Byrd (W.Va.), Cannon and Bible Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) The next issues are related to AFDC ("welfare", in the narrow sense of that word). Both of the votes we have on this sUbject relate to President Nixon's Family Assistance Plan (FAP) proposals in 1970 and 1972. The 1970 vote was on a motion to kill the FAP proposal. The motion was made by one of the FAP supporters (Long of Louisiana), some of whom had became convinced that they could not get the FAP accepted, and so sacrificed it to save the social security bill to which the FAP amendment was attached. Since this vote would there- fore not clearly indicate attitudes toward FAP or welfare, we will not consider it further. In 1972, several votes were taken relating to the FAP. The one included on our list was an attempt to increase benefits above the level proposed by Nixon. FOR AGAINST most LDs mast CRs most LRs most OSDs most NSDs Housing 172 AGAINST LRs Bellman, Pearson, Cook, Packwood, Stevens, Fang and Saxbe LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Byrd (W.Va.), (W.Va.), Bible, Cannon, Anderson (NgMex.), Randolph, Montoya, Fulbright, Symington, Burdick, Eagleton, Proxmire, Church and Magnuson The area of housing consists of several sub-areas; general housing appropriations, rent subsidies, and the Demonstration Cities program. We may consider rent subsidies first. There are three votes under this heading, from 1965, 1966 and 1967. FOR ALL SUBSIDIES most LDs most LRs HAVING A.MIXED RECORD CR3 Murphy, Miller, Dirksen and Morton (and perhaps Griffin) LRs Cooper, Prouty, Kuchel, Fang and Boggs (and perhaps Saltonstall) LDs Hartke, Young (Ohio), Bible and Hill AGAINST ALL SUBSIDIES most CR3 most OSDs CND Lausche NSD Hollings and Spong LDs Byrd (W.Va.), Gare, Cannon and Symington Another topic under the heading of housing programs is that of the Demonstration Cities program. There is one vote on this topic from 1966, on a vote to delete funds for the program from a bill. 173 FOR AGAINST most LDs most CRs most LRs most OSDs CND Lausche NSDs Spong and Hollings CRs Allott and Young (N.Dak.) LRs Boggs, Fang and Kuchel LDs Byrd (W.Va.) The sub-area of housing programs dealing with more general housing matters includes votes from 1961 (two), 1965, 1968, 1977 and 1978. The first two of these in a vote on general housing appropriations from 1961. FOR AGAINST most LDs CR Wiley LRs Boggs, Fang, Javits and OSDs Ervin, Jordan (N.C.) and Case (N.J.) Talmadge most CRs HAVING A MIXED RECORD most OSDs CND Lausche LR Keating LR Saltonstall, Smith (Me.), Aiken, LDs Ellender, Gore and Kerr Cooper, Prouty, Kuchel and Scott (Pa.) The next vote in this area is that on the establishment of the Department of Housing and Urban Development (1965). FOR AGAINST mast LDs most CR3 most LRs most OSDs CRs Miller and Allott CND Lausche OSD Jordan (N.C.) LRs Pearson and Cooper LDs Ellender, Hill, Sparkman and Bible The next vote on housing matters is that on the Housing and Urban Development Act of 1968, which provided aid to low-income people by buy or rent housing, flood insurance, riot insurance and other things. FOR most LDs mast LRs most CRs OSDs Harry Byrd Jr., Ervin, Jordan (N.C.) and Talmadge 174 AGAINST OSDs Stennis, Eastland, Holland and Russell CR Thurmond (a former OSD) The remaining housing votes come are a vote from 1977 and two from 1978, all involving votes on cutting general housing funds. CONSISTENTLY FOR HIGH-SPENDING most LDs LR Packwood, Hatfield, Weicker, Heinz, Javits, Brooke and Case (N.J.) (and perhaps Percy HAVING A MIXED RECORD CR3 Laxalt, Wallop, Hayakawa, Baker and Danforth LRs Stevens, Chafee, Stafford and Mathias NSDs Stone, Bentsen, Ford, Huddleston and Bumpers LDs Cannon, Melcher, Eagleton, Church, Hart (Col.), Haskell, Magnuson, Metzenbaum and Muskie Educating CONSISTENTLY FOR LOW-SPENDING most CRs most OSDs LRs Pearson, Bellman and Schweiker NSDs Chiles, Hollings and Johnston (La.) LDs Byrd (W.Va.) The votes in this areas may also be divided into sub-areas. The votes in 1960 (two), 1961 and 1965 form a natural group, as they are all rather similar votes dealing with elementary and secondary education. CONSISTENTLY HIGH-SPENDING most LDs LRs Cooper, Smith and Aiken (and perhaps CR Wiley) CONSISTENTLY LOW¥SPENDING most CR3 most OSDs CND Lausche and perhaps LR Beall Sr. 175 HAVING A MIXED RECORD CR3 Miller, Case (S.Dak.), Mundt, Dirksen, Carlson and Allott (and perhaps Martin) OSDs McClellan, Ervin, Jordan (N.C.) and Talmadge most LRs LDs Ellender, Sparkman, Johnston (S.C.), Long (La.) and Hayden Another vote on educational appropriations is on a bill providing funds generally for the Office of Education, from 1970. FOR AGAINST most LDs other CRs most LRs LRs Bellman, Packwood and Smith most NSDs (Me.) most OSDs CRs Hruska, Murphy, Jordan (Ida.), Cotton and Young (N. Dak.) Another kind of education vote is that from 1974, involving a formula for distribution of aid to elementary and secondary schools. AGAINST THE FORMULA FOR THE FORMULA most LDs mast CR3 most LRs most OSDs CRs Buckley, Roth and Griffin most NSDs LRs Cook, Packwood, Fang, Beall Jr., Hatfield, and Mathias LDs Ellender, Sparkman, Johnston (La.), Long (La.), Cannon, Bible, Montoya, Symington, Mansfield, Eagleton, Biden, Hartke, Proxmire, Haskell, Church, Bayh and Pastore The next vote is on aid to higher education. It is vote on the passage of bill, in 1963, providing funds for this purpose. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 most LRs most OSDs 176 CR3 Simpson, Hickenlooper, CND Lausche Miller, Dirksen, Young(N.Dak.), LR Cooper Carlson and Morton LDs Sparkman, Hill and Ellender OSD Jordan (N.C.) Health The next issue area to be considered is that of health or medical issues. This encompasses votes on medical "insurance" and votes on hospitals. Considering the former topic first, we can see that there are five votes on this topic. In 1960, 1962, 1964 and 1964 relatively similar proposals were put forth for what came to be known as "Medicare", a program for helping the elderly with their medical costs, financed partially or totally through the Social Security System. With the 1965 vote, the amendment was adopted and the bill (a social security bill) was passed. First we will count the first four votes together. FOR MEDICARE CONSISTENTLY AGAINST MEDICARE CONSISTENTLY most LDs most CRs LR Case (N.J.) most OSDs LR Pearson HAVING A MIXED RECORD LDs Ellender and Long (La.) CR3 Mundt and Young (N.Dak.) OSDs Russell, McClellan and Talmadge CND Lausche LDs Hill, Sparkman, Fulbright, Smathers, Kerr, Monroney, Byrd (W.Va.), Bible, Cannon, Anderson, Hayden and Randolph. Now we will consider the vote on passage of the 1965 social security bill, which included the last Medicare provision. 177 FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 most LRs mast OSDs OSDs Russell, McClellan and LR Pearson Talmadge LDs Ellender, Long (La.), Anderson CND Lausche (N.Mex.) and Harris CR Carlson The other medical votes relate to hospitals. The first is one an overriding the VBtO of a bill providing for additional hospital construction (1970). FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 most LRs LRs Packwood, Saxbe, Cooper, Smith most OSDs (Me.) and Goodell most NSDs CRs Dominick, Fannin, Murphy, Gurney, Cotton and Young (N.Dak.) The other vote on hospitals was on an amendment to a 1978 hospital cost control bill, which would authorize hospital revenue limits if certain goals were not met. FOR AGAINST most LDs mast CR3 LRs Bellman, Chafee, Stafford, most OSDs Javits, Brooke and Case (N.J.) most NSDs NSDs Chiles and Bumpers LRs Pearson, Packwood, Percy, CR Griffin Hatfield, Schweiker and Heinz CND Zorinsky LDs DeConcini, Long (La.), Melcher, Church and Inouye CEO and other poverty programs We may next consider the votes on the 0E0 (Office of Economic Opportunity--the War on Poverty). These votes fall into two groups. The first group consists of votes dealing with spending--dealing with the question of the establishment (1964) or continued existence 178 (1974) of the CEO or with appropriations to it (1965, 1968, 1969, 1971). CONSISTENTLY ON HIGH-SPENDING SIDE most LDs probably LRs Case (N.J.), Mathias, Stafford, Keating, Weicker, Percy and Kuchel HAVING A MIXED RECORD CRs Young (N.Dak.), Griffin, Dale and Baker (and probably Domenici) OSDs Allen, Ervin, Jordan (N.C.) and Talmadge LRs Pearson, Fang, Taft, Beall Jr., Smith (Me.), Cooper, Aiken, Prouty, Hatfield, Scott (Pa.), Schweiker, Javits and Brooke (and perhaps Stevens and Beall Jr.) NSD Hollings (and perhaps Nunn, Chiles, Spong, Johnston of La. and Huddleston) CONSISTENTLY ON LOW-SPENDING SIDE most CR3 most OSDs probably CND Lausche probably LRs Saltonstall, Bellman, and Boggs probably LDs Ellender and Hill The other group of CEO votes consists of those on proposals to permit governors to veto certain aspects of the program in their states (1965, 1967 and 1969). AGAINST THE VETO CONSISTENTLY most LDs most LRs Case (N.J.) and Javits (and probably Brooke and perhaps Mathias) FOR THE VETO CONSISTENTLY most CR3 most OSDs CND Lausche LRs Pearson, Boggs, Fang, Aiken and Prouty (and probably Saltonstall, Bellman, and Weicker) NSD Spong and Monroney LD Ellender (and probably Hill) HAVING A MIXED RECORD CR Young (N.Dak.) LRs Smith (Me.), Cooper and Scott (and probably Percy and perhaps Hatfield) LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Fulbright, Smathers and Byrd (W.Va.) 179 Another aspect of the poverty program which was voted upon was the Head Start program, on which we have a vote from 1968, regarding an increase in its funds. FOR most LDs most LRS NSDs Hollings and Spong CND Lausche CR3 Murphy, Dirksen and Griffin AGAINST most CRs most OSDs LRs Pearson, Boggs, Fang and Smith (Me.) LDs Ellender, Hill, Sparkman, Lang (La.), Smathers, Bible, Anderson, Hayden, Long (Mo.), Proxmire, Bartlett (Alsk.) and Church Related to three 0E0 votes is a 1971 vote on a bill to extend the GED and begin a child development program and legal ser- vices program for the poor. FOR most LDs most LRs most NSDs AGAINST most CR3 most OSDs LRs Pearson, Packwood, Smith (Me.), Taft, Saxbe and Stevens. There were two votes on the Legal Services program for the poor, both involving proposals to make it an independent corporation. The first, from 1972, was on an amendment to remove a provision from an OEO bill. 180 FOR AGAINST mast LDs mast CNDs LRs Stevens, Taft, Saxbe, most OSDs Scott (Pa.), Weicker, Percy, LRs Bellman, Cook, Packwood, Boggs, Hatfield, Stafford, Schweiker, Fang, Beall Jr., Cooper, Smith (Me.) Mathias, Javits, Brooke and and Aiken Case (N.J.) LDs Ellender, Sparkman, Long (La.), most NSDs and Byrd (W.Va.) OSD McClellan The second, from 1974, was a vote on cloture on a bill to achieve this same end. FOR AGAINST most LRs most CRs most NSDs most OSDs CR3 Roth, Griffin, Domenici and NSD Chiles Dole LDs Sparkman, Johnston (La.), OSD Talmadge Long (La.), Fulbright and Cannon Related votes from 1963 are those on a youth training bill, (amending the Manpower Training and Development Act of 1962), and the National Service Corps.. The former will be considered first. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CRs LRs Boggs, Fang, Beall Sr., most OSDs Kuchel, Scott (Pa.), Keating, LRs Saltonstall, Pearson, Smith Javits and Case (N.J.) (Me.) and Cooper CR.Morton LDs Ellender, Hill, Long (La.) and Johnston (S.C.) The other one is on passage of the National Service Corps bill. 181 FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 LRs Javits, Case (N.J.), most OSDs Keating, Fang and Cooper LRs Pearson, Boggs, Beall Sr., Prouty, Aiken, Smith (Me.), Kuchel and Scott (Pa.) LDs Engle, Young (0.), Gore, Johnston (S.C.), Long (La.), Smathers & Ellender Another vote is on a bill providing federal subsidies for child day care centers in 1976. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 and mast OSDs most LRs LRs Bellman, Stevens, Packwood, Fang most NSDs and Beall Jr. The subject CWO VOLES: LD Sparkman and NSD Bentsen of the School Lunch program for children involves a 1970 vote an amendment providing more generous distribu- tion standards and a 1975 vote on a bill to continue the program. FOR BOTH PROPOSALS most LDs most LRs AGAINST BOTH PROPOSALS most CRs NSD Hollings(and perhaps the other NSDs) AGAINST THE 1970 PROPOSAL BUT FOR THE 1975 ONE CRs Dale and Baker mast OSDs perhaps NSD Spong LRs Pearson and Scott (Pa.) LDs Sparkman and Bible Labor and HEW Dgpartmental Funds Another vote which is related to several others, but is one of a kind (on our list) is the 1976 vote an overriding a veto of a measure appropriating funds for the departments of Labor and HEW. FOR most LDs most LRs most NSDs OSDs Stennis, Eastland, and Talmadge CR3 McClure, Young (N.Dak.), Domenici, Roth and Baker ‘Mas§_Transit 182 AGAINST most CRs OSDs Harry Byrd Jr., McClellan and Allen LR Packwood LDs Ribicoff and Proxmire There are a number of votes related to federal aid to mass transit. highway trust funds to be spent on local mass transit. The first votes in this group involve a proposal to allow Two of them (from 1973 and 1975) propose allowing the funds to be used for local mass transit generally. The third proposal (1972) was to allow the funds to be used specifically to aid rail transportation. FOR ALL PROPOSALS most LDs most LRs perhaps CRs Dominick, Bennett, Brock, Miller and Allott FOR THIS 1972 PROPOSAL, WITH A MIXED RECORD ON THE OTHERS LDs Metcalf, Symington, Mondale and Muskie (and perhaps Clark of la.) LRs Beall Jr. and Taft perhaps NSD Nunn CRS Buckley and Griffin (and perhaps Baker) AGAINST ALL PROPOSALS most CR3 most OSDs most NSDs LR Stevens LDs Byrd (W.Va.), Cannon, Randolph, Sparkman and Long (La.) (and perhaps Bible, Anderson (N.Mex.), Montoya, Fulbright and Bayh) FOR THE 1972 PROPOSAL; AGAINST THE OTHERS CRs Fannin and Hruska (and perhaps Gurney) OSD Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.) LD Church, Stevenson and Humphrey (and perhaps Eagleton and Hughes) 183 This discussion leads us to consider the beginnings of Federal aid to mass transit, and the vote on passing the bill estab- lishing the program in 1963. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 LRs Javits, Case (N.J.) most OSDs Keating, Kuchel and Scott LRs Saltonstall, Pearson, Boggs, (Pa.) Cooper, Smith (Me.), Aiken, Prouty and Beall Sr. LDs Hill, McGee, McIntyre and Bayh Government Aid to Business Another group of issues includes votes on various matters, all of which involve government aid to partnership with business. These included aid to SST, aid to Lockheed and establishing the Communications Satellite company. The first of these is the issue of government aid to the construction of a Supersonic Transport (SST) airplane. There are two votes here an amendment to bills, one to delete funds from a bill in 1970 and the other to restore funds in 1971. FOR SST CONSTRUCTION AGAINST SST CONSTRUCTION OSDs Stennis, Eastland, mast LDs McClellan and Talmadge (and most LRs perhaps Russell) CRs Jordan (Ida.), Hansen and Griffin NSD Hollings (and perhaps Murphy and Roth) LRS Bellman, Pearson. Ellender, NSD Spong (and perhaps Bentsen and Boggs, Saxbe and Mathias (and Chiles) perhaps Stevens, Beall Jr- OSD Harry Byrd Jr., Ervin, Jordan and Taft) (N.C.) and Allen (and perhaps LDs Ellender, Sparkman, Long Holland) (La.), Byrd (W.Va.), Cannon, Bible, Randolph, Gravel, Magnuson, Jackson, McGee, Inouye and Moss (and perhaps Yarborough and Dodd) most CR3 HAVING A MIXED RECORD CR3 Dominick, Cotton and Miller LRs Cook, Fang and Smith (Me.) LDs Proxmire, Muskie, Symington and Anderson (N.Mex.) 184 The next vote is on a bill to provide loan guarantees to Lockheed Aircraft Corporation (1971). FOR most CRs OSDs Eastland, Stennis, Allen and Talmadge LRs Pearson, Cook, Packwood, Boggs, Fang, Cooper, Scott (Pa.), Mathias, Javits and Case (N.J.) NSD Hollings LDS Ellender, Sparkman, Long (La.), Byrd (W.Va.), Cannon, Bible, Randolph, Metcalf, Gravel, McIntyre, Inouye, Williams (N.J.), Moss, Cranston, Tunney and Humphrey AGAINST CRs Goldwater. Buckley, Curtis, Dominick, Jordan (Ida.) and Griffin OSDs Harry Byrd Jr., Ervin, Jordan and McClellan NSDs Chiles and Spong LRs Bellman, SaXbe, Smith (Me.), Aiken, Taft, Beall Jr., Weicker, Percy, Hatfield, Schweiker, and Brooke most LDs Another somewhat similar vote is that on the Communications Satellite bill in 1962. FOR most CR3 most Lrs most LDs OSD Holland The vote was on cloture of the filibuster. AGAINST CRs Goldwater and Tower most OSDs (incl. Thurmond) LDs Ellender, Hill, Sparkman, Johnston (S.C.), Long (La.), Fulbright, Gore, Kefauver, Yarborough, Byrd (W.Va.), Cannon, Bible, Hayden, Burdick, Gruening, Bartlett (Alas.), Morse, McGee Neuberger, Carroll, Young (Ohio), McNamara and Douglas 185 Wage and Price Controls Another issue area is that of wage and price controls. There are three votes in this area. The first vote, on extending presidential authority that had already been granted in this area, is from 1971. FOR AGAINST most LDS CR Goldwater most LRs LDs McGovern, Harris, Hartke, most NSDs Fulbright and Proxmire most OSDS most CR3 The other votes on wage and price controls were from 1974. They are both on tabling (killing) two amendments to a bill on the Council for International Economic Policy. One vote was on killing an amendment to give the President standby powers to use wage and price controls in selected industries, under certain conditions. The other was on killing an amendment to continue the Cost of Living Council to monitor inflation and give the President power to enforce agreements on price increases when controls ended. The only one to oppose killing the former, while favoring the killing of the latter was Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.). Otherwise, the two votes scale perfectly. AGAINST KILLING BOTH CR Roth OSDS Eastland and Stennis NSD Chiles LRs Mathias, Javits and Case (N.J.) most LDs 186 FOR KILLING SELECTIVE WAGE FOR KILLING BOTH PRICE CONTROLS; AGAINST KILLING COST OF LIVING COUNCIL AND most CR3 PRICE INCREASES ENFORCEMENT OSDs Allen, Ervin and Talmadge NSDs Nunn and Hollings OSD McClellan LRs Stevens, Pearson, Bellman. LRs Beall Jr., Taft and Fang, Aiken, Scott (Pa.), Weicker, Stafford Percy, Hatfield, Schweiker and NSDs Bentsen and Huddleston Brooke LDs McGovern, Cranston, Muskie, LDs Gravel, Eagleton, Hartke, Inouye, Bayh, McIntyre and Proxmire, Burdick, Abourezk, Clark Byrd (W.Va.) (Ia.), Tunney and Metzenbaum Fuel Rationing and Related Programs Another issue area is that of rationing. The only votes on it are those on fuel rationing. These consist of one vote (from 1973) on rationing as such, and two votes (from 1974 and 1975) on general energy programs which include rationing proposals. The vote from 1973 on rationing alone is on a proposal to provide for stand-by rationing authority. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 most NSDs OSDS Harry Byrd Jr. (Va.), Allen LRs Weicker and Case (N.J.) and Ervin OSDs Stennis, Eastland and most LRs McClellan LDs Long (La.), Cannon, Bible, Montoya, Church, Biden, Hartke, Bayh and Tunney The votes from 1974 and 1975 are on energy programs includ- ing provisions relating to stand-by rationing plans, oil price control, conservation and relaxation of pollution standards. FOR most LDs NSDs Huddleston and Chiles (and perhaps Bumpers, Ford and Morgan) LRs Javits, Brooke, Case (N.J.), and Stafford (and perhaps Aiken) OSDS McClellan and Talmadge) HAVING A MIXED RECORD CR3 Roth, Young (N.Dak.), Griffin and Baker OSDS Stennis (and probably Allen and Ervin) LRs Stevens, Packwood, Scott (Pa.), Percy, Hatfield and Mathias (and probably Cook and Schweiker) NSDs Nunn, Chiles and Hollings LDs Montoya, Gravel, McGee and Abourezk 187 AGAINST OSDs Harry Byrd (Va.) and Eastland LRs Bellman, Pearson, Fang, Beall Jr., Taft and Weicker NSD Bentsen and Johnston (La.) LD Long (La.) Federal Energy Administration (FEA) The next issue area involves two votes from 1976, on amend— ment to a bill dealing with the Federal Energy Administration. One amendment set mandatory energy-conservation standards for new build— ings. FOR most LDs most LRs NSDs Nunn, Hollings, Ford and Huddleston CR Laxalt The other vote was on an to gather information on energy. FOR mast LDs LRS Javits, Brooke, Case (N.J.), Heinz and Schweiker NSDs Nunn, Chiles, Hollings, Johnston (La.), Ford, Huddleston and Bumpers AGAINST most CRs most OSDS LRs Stevens, Bellman, Fang and Hatfield NSDs Stone, Chiles, Bentsen, Morgan, Johnston (La.) and Bumpers LDs Long (La.), Metcalf and Pastore amendment to establish an agency AGAINST most CR3 mast OSDS most LRS NSDs Stone, Bentsen and Morgan LDs Long (La.), Gravel, McGee and Glenn 188 No-Fault Insurance Votes on no-fault insurance constitute the next group. These are proposals to require states to adopt no-fault plans. Here we have them from 1972, 1974 and 1976. FOR ALL AGAINST ALL most LDs most CR3 most LRs most OSDs CR Griffin most NSDs LDs Gravel and Sparkman HAVING A MIXED RECORD CRs Bennett and Brock LRs Bellman, Packwood, Beall Jr., Taft, Scott (Pa.), Stafford and Mathias LDs Cannon, Bible, Randolph, Montoya, Hartke, Moss, Church and McGovern perhaps NSD Spong. Antitrust Law Another vote is that on a bill to make the antitrust laws stricter (1976). FOR AGAINST mast LDs most CRs most LRs most OSDS OSD Harry Byrd Jr. and Talmadge CR3 Miller, Dole, Domenici, rRoth, Baker and Griffin Airline Deregulation Another issue area concerning the regulation of business is that of airline deregulation. This area contains two votes, both on the deregulation bill of 1978. The first is on an amendment pro- viding for broad areas of freedom in regard to market entry. AGAINST OSDs Harry Byrd Jr., Stennis, Eastland and Talmadge CR3 Scott (Va.), Young (N.Dak.), Schmitt, Griffin and Danforth CND Zorinsky LR Stevens NSD Bentsen LDs Sparkman, Byrd (W.Va.), Randolph, Melcher, Burdick, Magnuson, Jackson and Stevenson 189 FOR most CR3 most NSDs most LRS mast LDs LDs DeConcini, Long (La.), Sasser, Byrd (W.Va.), Randolph, Gravel, Glenn, Stevenson, McGovern and Abourezk. Another amendment to the bill concerned job security for airline workers. The amendment proposed giving displaced workers preference in hiring instead of compensation, as then provided in the bill. AGAINST most LDs LRs Stevens, Weicker, Stafford, Schweiker, Mathias, Javits, Brooke and Case (N.J.) NSDs Stone, Chiles, Ford and Huddleston CRs Laxalt, Scott, Domenici, Griffin and Danforth Consumer Protection FOR mast CRs mast OSDS CND Zorinsky LRS Bellman, Pearson, Chafee, Hatfield and Percy NSDs Nunn, Bentsen, Hollings, Morgan and Bumpers. Next, the votes on a consumer protection agency will be con- sidered. These involve bills that proposed to establish an agency to represent consumers before other regulatory agencies, from 1972 and 1974. FOR BOTH mast LDs most LRs most NSDs CR Roth (and perhaps Domenici) 190 HAVING A MIXED RECORD AGAINST BOTH CRS Griffin and Dale (and most CR3 perhaps Miller ) most OSDs LR Fang (and perhaps Boggs, perhaps NSD Johnston (La.) Saxbe, Prouty, Smith [Me.] LR Taft and Cooper) LDs Bible, Long (La.), Sparkman LD Cannon and Ellender There are two more votes involving consumer protection. The first is a vote on standard weights and measures on labels, from 1966. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CR3 most LRs most OSDS OSD Harry Byrd Jr. LRs Boggs, Cooper, Scott (Pa.) and Prouty The remaining consumer protection vote is on a motion to kill an amendment to a bill which provided for criminal penalties for violations of consumer product safety measures from 1972. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CRs most LRs mast OSDs NSD Bentsen LRS Stevens, Fang, Cooper, Smith (Me.), Saxbe, Prouty, Aiken, Scott (Pa.) and Stafford NSDs Hollings and Spong LDs Ellender and Inouye National Consumer Co-operative Bank There is one vote on this issue, on the passage of the bill establishing the bank, in 1978. FOR most LDs most LRs NSDs Bumpers, Ford and Morgan CR3 Hayakawa, Thurmond, Griffin, Dale and Baker OSD Talmadge 191 AGAINST most CR3 most OSDS CND Zorinsky NSD Bentsen, Chiles and Huddleston LRs Bellman, Packwood and Chafee LDS Sasser, Proxmire and Glenn Occupational Safety_and Health Administration (OSHA) There are two votes concerning the regulations of this agency. The first, from 1977, was on an amendment requiring economic impact statements to be prepared by OSHA when it issued new regula- tions. AGAINST most LDs NSDs Stone, Hollings, Huddleston and Bumpers LRS Mathias, Schweiker, Javits, Case (N.J.) and Brooke FOR most CRs most OSDS LRs Stevens, Packwood, Chafee, Weicker, Hatfield, Stafford and Heinz NSDs Nunn, Bentsen, Chiles, Margan, Johnston (La.) and Ford LDs DeConcini, Sparkman, Cannon and Church The other vote was an amendment from 1978 which provided that small businesses with a good safety record would be exempt from OSHA regulations. AGAINST most LDs most LRs NSD Huddleston OSD Talmadge FOR most CR3 most OSDs LRs Stevens, Hatfield and Weicker NSDs Nunn, Bentsen, Hollings, Chiles, Morgan and Bumpers LDs Sparkman, Sasser, Cannon, Randolph, Church, McIntyre and Biden 192 Environmental Issues This broad area includes votes on air pollution control. water pollution control, highway beautification, the Alaska pipeline and strip mining. In the area of air pollution control, there are four votes: one from 1970 and three from 1976. Two of the ones from 1976 consist of two amendments to a bill, one removing the require- ment that polluters not make unpolluted air worse, and another moving automakers' deadline for compliance one year sooner. These two votes almost scale. The only exception was New South Democrat Stone (who favored both amendments). AGAINST DELETION OF NON- AGAINST DELETION OF NON- DEGRADATION PROPOSAL AND DEGRADATION PROPOSAL BUT AGAINST FOR HASTENING OF HASTENING OF DEADLINE DEADLINE most LRS most LDs CR3 Curtis, Hansen, Buckley, LRs Hatfield, Packwood, McClure, Domenici, Roth and Baker Weicker, Mathias, Brooke NSDs Nunn, Chavez and Morgan and Case (N.J.) LDs Randolph, Montoya, Eagleton, NSD Bumpers Gravel, Burdick, Stevenson, McGee, Humphrey and Mondale (and perhaps FOR DELETION 0F NON- Symington and Inouye) DEGRADATION PROPOSAL AND (and probably Biden, Hartke, Mondale AGAINST HASTENING OF and Hart of Mich.) DEADLINE most CRs most OSDs most NSDs LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Byrd (W.Va.) and Moss A third vote on this same Clean Air bill was on an amendment which deleted from the bill the provision relaxing current standards for nitrous oxide emissions. 193 FOR AGAINST most LDs mast CR3 LRs Javits, Case (N.J.) most OSDs Brooke, Mathias, Hatfield, most NSDs Weicker and Packwood LRs Bellman, Pearson, Stevens, Fang, NSD Stone Beall Jr., Taft, Scott (Pa.), Percy and Stafford LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Cannon, Randolph, Montoya, Eagleton, Gravel, Church, McIntyre, Burdick, McGee and Inouye The 1970 air pollution vote involved a proposed amendment easing the appeals process for the pollution deadlines for automakers. AGAINST FOR most LDs most CR3 most LRs OSD Russell, Holland, Eastland and most NSDs Stennis OSDS Harry Byrd Jr., Allen, LRs Hatfield and Packwood McClellan and Talmadge LD Fulbright CRs Murphy, Allen, Dominick and Mundt Another kind of pollution is water pollution. There is one vote on it on our list, a vote on the Water Quality Act of 1965. It is on an amendnent to delete the provision which gave the Secre- tary of HEW authority to set water quality standards. AGAINST DELETION FOR DELETION most LDs mast CR3 mast LRs OSDs Robertson, McClellan and mast LRs Talmadge most OSDs LD Mansfield CR3 Williams (Del.), Cotton, Jordan (Id.), Young (N.D.), Miller and Allott CND Lausche Another vote on a similar issue was on passage of a highway beautification bill (1965). 194 FOR AGAINST most LDs most CRs most LRs most OSDs CRs Fannin, Murphy, Dominick, LD Ellender Williams (Del.), Jordan (Ida.), Cotton. Young (N.Dak.) and Dirksen CND Lausche The next vote on environmental issues is an the issue of restraining strip mining. It is on an amendment from 1973 which provides for federal regulation of it. FOR AGAINST most LDs most CRs most LRs mast OSDS most NSDs LDs Long (La.), Bible, Cannon and CR3 Young (N.Dak.) and Roth Moss OSD Allen. There were two votes on the 1973 bill concerning the con— struction of the Alaska pipeline. The first was antiproposed amend- ment to delay construction until after further environmental studies had been made. The second vote was on a proposed amendment to bar judicial review of environmental aspects of the bill, and authorize the granting of permissions to begin construction of the pipeline. AGAINST FOR most LDs mast CRs LRs Cook, Packwood, Aiken, most OSDS Percy, Hatfield, Stafford, most NSDs Mathias, Javits and Case LRs Bellman, Stevens, Fang, Beall (N.J.) Jr., Taft, Saxbe, Scott (Pa.), CR3 Buckley, Gurney, McClure, Weicker, Schweiker and Brooke Roth and Dale LDs Sparkman, Long (La.), Byrd (W.Va.), Cannon, Bible, Randolph, Gravel and Hartke 195 The next issue area concerns nuclear energy--specifica11y, the construction of nuclear reactors. There are two votes here. The first is an an amendment to a 1961 nuclear energy bill to cut funds for a new reactor in Hanford, Washington. FOR AGAINST most LDs mast CR3 LRS Javits, Aiken, Smith most OSDS (Me.), Cooper and Kuchel LRs Saltonstall, Boggs, Fang, Beall Sr., Scott (Pa.), Keating and Cannon LDs Ellender, Long (La.) and Smathers. The other vote is on an amendment to cut reduced funds for construction of a breeder reactor at Clinch River, Tennessee. FOR CUT AGAINST CUT most LDs most CRs most LRs most OSDs most NSDs CND Zorinsky LRs Schweiker, Heinz and Stevens NSDs Johnston (La.) and Huddleston LDs Long (La.), Sasser, Cannon, Eagleton, Melcher, Burdick, Magnuson, Jackson, Bayh and Stevenson Aggregation of Cleavages(into Cleavage Sets) Having summarized the alignments on each vote in this way, we may now try to group the resulting cleavages into larger groups which involve several issues. To simplify the following discussion, we will, on the basis of the common perceptions of the significance of various issues, and the way groups of Senators lined up on them, identify a "conservative" ("right") and "liberal" ("left") side of most of the issues, in the ordinary sense of these terms. We may 196 recall that, at the start of this study, this common classification, used in the press and everyday conversation, was discussed. Generally speaking, the liberal or leftist favors the use of govern- ment to achieve equality of condition, while the conservative or rightist opposes this because he is generally less favorable to government activity—-at least if this is used to achieve equality of condition. This distinction is made solely for the sake of simplifying the following discussion, and further meaning should not be read into the terms. Consequently, further precision in these definitions is unnecessary. During the time period covered by this study, liberals favored higher spending than did conservatives on food stamps, social security, unemployment compensation, AFDC, food stamps (including those for strikers), rent subsidies and other housing programs, education, health programs, public works programs (especially those for providing public works jobs), the 0E0 and other poverty programs (the National Service Corps, Youth Training, Youth Conservation Corps, Area Redevelopment), child care (including day care), legal services for the poor, mass transit, and general appropriations for the Departments of Labor and HEW, and other "social welfare" spend- ing, and the overall budget. (Sometimes, conservatives opposed the program in question entirely.) It follows that liberals were more apt to favor expanding the coverage of these programs, to favor setting minimum benefit levels, or raising them, and to favor easier eligibility requirements for recipients of a program; conservatives 197 were more apt to feel the opposite way. The governor's veto of the CEO, which would cause less money to be spent on it (as well as protecting states' rights) was generally opposed by liberals and favored by conservatives. Liberals generally favored more regulation of business of the kinds represented by wage-price controls, rationing, energy conservation legislation, a consumer protection agency, consumer product safety and labeling legislation, antitrust laws, and airline deregulation, while favoring mandating no-fault insurance. Also, liberals tended to favor stricter legislation regarding pollution and environmental concerns, and stricter enforcement of it. Tax legislation presents a more confusing picture. Conser- vatives tended to want lower taxes but also to want balanced budgets, and so often to advocate a high tax position; the first desire, for lower taxes, has tended to win out since about 1977, while the second, for balanced budgets, tended to be stronger through 1975. Liberals were similarly torn between a desire to tax business and a desire to administer a stimulus to the economy; liberals especially opposed tax cuts that are not heavily weighted in favor of the lower income groups. All of this applies mainly to income taxes, but some of it applies to other tax proposals as well. Liberals seem to want the tax-benefit ratio of social security to be skewed in relatively egalitarian direction. In the earlier descriptions of the alignments on the various votes by issue areas, it was usually the case that the Senators 198 could be grouped into those who were consistently on one side of the issue, those who were on the other, and those with mixed records. We have just identified what the conservatives and liberal positions were on each side of most issues; we can regard the groupings as being groups of "conservatives", "liberals" and "moderates". Furthermore, this placing of them into these three groupings means that there have been two cleavages identified in each issue area: one separating the conservatives from the moderates, and the second, to its "left", separating the moderates from the liberals. Therefore, we may henceforth identify each cleavage as the "right- ward" or "leftward" cleavage associated with a given issue area. Now we may attempt to aggregate the various cleavages in the different issue areas discussed above into sets of similar cleavages, each set presumably indicating a major underlying ideo- logical change. The sets of cleavages, along with the adjuncts in each set and changes within each set, are listed below. Correspondences Between the Cleavaggs From the Voting Records and the Cleavages From the Theoretical Model The first set of cleavages (the main labor, rightward food stamps and rightward education, health and housing cleavages, among others) seem to correspond to that cleavage from the model which separates the "Left-Progressive" column from the "Right-New Deal" column. The cleavage from the model is the one which generally cor- responds ta the conventional notion of what the "conservative" 199 ooma>aa~u Lo you vuwsu mesa .uo>o:o= .uozuo some sou: uguun aomu>co~u Lo wave or» era away we: coo o: .ezzh .aowa>co~u ones» we usuuu ozu cu on. .nuwa>au~u no you unuuu may no uuod as» on may: oz: .ocauudpaaux mononu— osu away 0‘ you uouuu can on. ouwu>ao~u me you outu cooauon oocououuuv unaumua och .uuguo room can: o—uuo aoma>uo~u uo can: any any as» can a: 00:0: .aoco nauuna ouozu uo azuuu ago 0» one: uuluou 05a no uuo~ as» on one: or: cocoa—asaox ~nuop«~ can nausea-on ~au0¢- anal unsa a« you omega 0:» can ooma>ao~o Lo you many cooauon oucuuuuuuv annulus use .nnaA Lo ouo> xau auuuaaoa —n_occ use use Auao ouupceuou who. can or: oocwaofi—n couao_oouaou _no~ tray noxua oucuoauou oecc Avuuauuauv nauou ccuuu>uun=ou senor uzu .Avuuauuo_v nauseous. cauuuuuCuuuucc acuxaezurouzaeaz oca.Avuuauuo~v .920 new uneven duuocow .Avuuauuouv huuusuoo uuuuom .ua~ou mad—oaua axuu~< one as. Anna: uuuouv ena— mo oeuo> couusuuoa yum .Avuaa lumu~v mace oxuoa u«_a:a .coa~ «a ooauuucu uuaum poo: as» .AsdquCQ as» mcunu~uuoa«~ co ouo> o~o_ usuv ausocafl _oocuu .Aoco vuuDuLOu ozuv uaqvuaaan “can .Avu-tuuuuv ououo> a.uo:uo>ou owe on» .ANNom huh-39 -«ataa. Aauom uncouuqz ozu .oouauu ccuaauuo:060n .quu see cause .uaauxu uaouo~ a ou .uca .u:«=«l auuuu vac gonna -ogmauv case to mono» eoaasaaoa as. 0;“ .uc02ac_o>uvo¢ nou< use u«:uo—oaa< an own .neo_ :« auacuuh can: ou van was “nasal nucolu unusuauh can acosao~o>un boson -eczo means-us ease» .__aa oeuasoae-u ease» as» .93: Lo acuisuuuauuoo 0:» .mnm— _a uuo> x-u 0600:“ osu .Avuua auewuuv oucauoqumn ~qu«voa .Auuuauswuuv mouvumnaa use» .Auuaauswquv vodka: monoco— azu :« woao> couunuavo .A:o«u um—muxon coda: .ucouxo ascend a cu .vcu .-o_ can ooo— cu connotes“ one: Ialucua on: auoxduum you unauaa poem .doa— Cu ow=u0>ou oum3uaaeqcus wovcmaxo .ooo~ Cu couueacocsco ucoazoanocs >__I«OUAuov mosxz_ t:;:~ Luce .Avumzaquuv auuusuoo _cuucm .Acuz>mo_u vacauzmuuv mascua coon .nson .z .cccu van ulna .m vac A.uian .m 30: ..nao¢ .ucOu ouluuufloo vauv ..nna¢ .Aud .0: .ulon ouu 033 .m Du: Asauuacav use .oson .z .ucou ..nloa .w vac ..aao¢ .ocou ..oao¢ .num aloe .u> .030: nag use: or: ..-Ian .a«~ alo- .ulon a«~ anon anon .m :02 .uaon .z .mcoa new Aafidnscav neon .m u_o .o> can .uaox .a«~ ..nno¢ .acoo ..uson .a«~ macoEEcu “om auu>co_u c“ v0v3~oc~ aaua>ao~u oouu>uo_u we you so ououucom Lo acoecwu~< uaaE:z aom aww>wo~u Aauom owu>aa~uv nuwn>uo_u Lo oco«»cwoum&0000 00 0000 00000 000 00000 000 .0000: .000 0000 00 0000 0:0 00 000 0000>0000 00 000 00000 000 00 00000 000 00 0003 00: 0000 :0000000 0>000>000000 0000 0000000 000 00000 000 00 00u0>0000 000 00 00000 0000 000000 0000>0000 00000 00 00000000 00 0000000000 00H .A30000 0000 000000300 00000000 000 00 0.000000 000 000000 000 000;: ._0000 00000000000 000 00 000000000 0000000 000 00 00 0w0>0000 0000 0000 00000000 08000 00 .0000 00 .0000 0003 00000 000 00 5000 00 000 .000000 000 00 0000 000000 000 00 0000 .0000 0000 000 00 .0000>0000 00000 .0000000 00 .A000 00000 000 00 0000 000 00 000 000000 0000 000000 00000 000 00 00000 000 00 000 000 000000 000 00 0000 000 00 000 00000000 000 .000>00 000 000000: .00000000 .000000 0000000000: 00000.. 0a.: 000;: .0000» 0:0 0c 0000 000 use 000 000000 000 00 00000 00 000 00000000 000 .0000: 000 .00000u ..0>.3 00 00>nv 000000800 0000000 0000 "0000>0000 00 000 000000 000 000000 0000 00 0000000 “a00000 000 0000 00 000 00000 000 000: 000000 000 000000 000 000000 00>0v 000 000000 000 0003 00000 000 0000 000000 000:. 300000000 0:0 000.3000000 00o0 .000: 000000 A00000000 0000 000 0000 000 000000000 0000-000: 000 .Anso0v 0000000 000000 .00003000000 0000: 000000 .00>00 .0000 .00003000000 00000000 000000 .0000 .>00m 0me0 000 >000mm .0000 00000000 .0000x0 00000. 0 00 000 00n00 000 00000 .0000 00000000 0003 .000 .00003000000 00000> .>o¢ Duo .00003000000 .oao .0000 0>0000000uou 00000000 .00: .000000000 00:00:00 .000000 000000 0 00 000 000000000 0000 .00000000 00000-0003 .0000 .m 000 300 0 000 .0000 .0000 0000 .0000 .0000 .0000 .2 .0000 000000: 000 .000n .0 000 0000 000 .000: .0000 000' .0000 .000 0000 000 .0000 .000 0000 ..0000 .0 000 000 0 000000000 ..0000 .2 .0000 ..000¢ .0000 0000 .0001 .0000 0000 000 .0000 .2 .0000 ..0000 .m 000 0000 ..0009 .m 30: .0> ..000x .000 ..0I0a .000 .0000 .0 000 0:0 .0000 .0 so: ..0000 .0__ .ms ..0000 .0.— .0000 .0 000 :00 0 000000000 000 .000: .0000 0000 .0> ..0000 .m 302 ..000m .000 ..0l0n .000 .0000 .000 000.0 000 .0000 .m :02 .00 ..000K .000 0000 ..0l0n .m 000 0000 ..0000 .0000 :00 0 00w0>0000 00 00m 00 0000000» 00 00000000< 0000:: 00m 000>000u 00005500 00m 0w0>00~u 00 00000000 00w0>0000 201 .000000000 00000000 000 00000000 0000 .000: .000 >000 .0000000 0m0>0000 000 00 0000000 0000 000 .0000 000 0000 000 000 .0000 .x .0000 .000: 000 0000 0000 000I0000000 >000 00 .000000 00 0000000 .000000 0000000000000 .An000ucoo00 ..0l0: .m 000 .0> .000 0000 000 :000 0000 0000000 0>00 0000> 00000 00 000m 0000000: Anoo0 000 0000 .0000» 0000a 00000000a ..000¢ .0000 .0000 .000 n0 .0000 .2 .0000 000 .0000 .m 000 ..000¢ .0000 .000> x00 woo0 000 0000 0:0 000 00 000000000 ..000¢ .000 .0000 .m :02 000 00000000 00000000 0000 000 .0000000 ..0600 .m :02 0000 .0> 0000 000000000 0000 00 .000 0000» 000 0000000 0000 000 0500 ..0I0a .000 0000 000 .0I0a .000 0-00 N0 .0l0o .000 0000 000 .000000000 00000 .0000 .000 0l00 .0000 :00 .000000 000000 0 00 .000 0000000 000- ..0l00 .m 00o .0> .000 0000 000 000 00000 5030000 .0008000 000000000 0300 ..000¢ .0000 .0000 .000 0000 _0 .000: .m .0000 .000 0000 000 000 300 0 000 .000: .000 0000 .000: .000 300 0 ..0000 .m :02 0000 .0: ..0fl0a .m.z 0000 .0000 000: 0030000: 000 00030000: ..0E0n .w 000 000! ..000m .000 000! 000 .00000000m 00000000000000 .900 .00000000 ..000¢ .0000 000! ..0|0: .000 5000 Q0 .000¢ .0000 >000 000 .0000 .m 000 0.28 .m 302 .0000 000000000 ..000¢ .000 0000 000 0000 000000000000 00000000 0500 .000: .0000 0600 .0> ..0I0n .000 o .0500 0000300000 04003 000000 .0 302 000 00000000>00 00000000 .000000 000000 0 00 .000 .0000 .000 .0> .0000 .m 000 00000000 000000000 000 0000 000 000 000 0000 000 .0000 .0000 ..0000 .000 0 00000500 000 0w0>000u 00 00000000 00¢0>000o 00w0>000o 00 00m 00 00000000 00 00000m00< 000302 000 0¢0>000u 202 —libera1" dichotomy means in modern American politics-—i.e., Ameri- can politics since the coming of the New Deal. As has been said, it is commonly defined as a cleavage between pro— and anti-New Dealers, but as has also been noted, many of the anti-New Deal conservatives", from circa 1937 on had been New Deal supporters earlier, or had at least accepted the "basics" of the New Deal (the Social Security Act and the labor legislation). More- over, much of the liberal agenda over which they fought dealt with post-New Deal issues. The examination of the voting records makes this point still more strongly. The growth in many of the programs for which the liberals fought wasrun:achieved until Lyndon Johnson's early Great Society programs (the establishment of the food stamp program on a permanent basis, and Medicare), or even later in Johnson's term (large Social Security and AFDC increases) or still later (the later growth of the food stamp program in the Nixon era). Hence, in a way we can say that the "New Deal" liberals did not attain the completion of most of their goals until the Great Society (or later), and these really should be called "Great Society lib- erals". However, this would cause confusion with those we have been calling Great Society liberals, indicating the need for another name change, and such a modification in terminology will not be attempted at so a late a point in the paper. In any case, this cleavage in question seems to have been the dominant one in American politics since the start of the late New Deal (circa 1937), when most "progressive" Republicans and many 203 former New Deal Democrats (especially in the South) joined the "con- servative" Republicans and "conservative" and "irreconciliable" Democrats (mostly Southern) in a "conservative coalition". In 1937, it sought to moderate pro-union trends in labor relations and reduce spending on relief; in the 19605, its goals were not very much dif- ferent, and the same can be said for those of its liberal opponents. The second set of cleavages (the AFDC; the leftward food stamps and the leftward rent and 0E0 cleavages, among others) seem to correspond to that cleavage from the model which separates the "New Deal liberals” proper (Right and Left wings considered as a group) from the "Great Society liberals" (Right and Left wings, con- sidered as a group). As the discussion of the first set of cleavages suggested, these cleavages over "Great Society" issues were really in some ways post-Great Society issues, just as the cleavages over the "New Deal" issues were really over post—New Deal issues, even Great Society issues. To some extent, the new era is carried in the womb of the old. As the New Dealers were enacting most of their program in the Great Society years, so the Great Society groups were achieving some of their goals (rent subsidies, greater AFDC spend- ing, expanded food stamps programs) in the late Johnson and post- Johnson years. To some extent, this is still the cleavage Phillips was say- ing was replacing the "New Deal" cleavage in the 19503 and especially the 19605, although it now appears that he was also referring to our New Deal cleavage replacing earlier ones. 204 The third set of cleavages (the leftward social security, general spending and public works jobs cleavages, the 1977 social security and 1971 corporate tax cleavages) seems to correspond to that cleavage on the model which separated rightist (Republican) liberals (New Deal and Great Society varieties considered together) from leftist (Democratic) liberals (New Deal and Great Society varieties considered together). This cleavage appears to have been around since the New Deal, or at least since the rise of liberal Republicans as a distinct group, but it generally seems to have been a subordinate one, which is usually obscured by the more Prominent first two cleavages. In any case, it does not seem to be one much talked about in political literature. The fourth set of cleavages (the wage-price control and rationing cleavages, and others) seems to correspond to the cleavage from the model which separates the relatively libertarian rows from the relatively statist rows, separating in particular the classical liberals (conservatives) from the statist Right-Progressives (the Rightist corporate liberals). Of the first five sets of cleavages, this is the only one which involves the liberty dimension rather than the equality dimension. The history of this cleavage has seldom been enunciated, as its nature and separate existence have seldom been perceived in political literature. The fifth set of cleavages (the legal services, Consumer Protection Agency and rightward 0E0 cleavages, among others) seems to correspond to the cleavage on the model which separate the Left- Progressive and Right-Progressive columns. This cleavage in the 205 model is the one which would seem at first to be the principal one of the Progressive Era, but from other viewpoints, the matter is not so clear. In any case, it is the one Hofstadter focuses on. It most clearly showed itself in that era in income tax questions, and seems to represent the principal egalitarian-inegalitarian cleavage of the antitrust struggles. (The fourth set of cleavages, in the voting records, discussed above, may represent the libertarian- statist cleavage of the antitrust struggles.) However, the program on the left side of this cleavage did not become implemented until the middle New Deal (circa 1935-37) in the form of higher taxes, especially on business, utility company divestiture laws, and a less tolerant attitude toward big business under the antitrust laws. And soon (circa 1937), people were distracted by another cleavage--the first one discussed here. Nonetheless, this fifth cleavage has occasionally managed to show itself, principally on tax questions and questions of the regulation of business, but also in certain aspects of the poverty program (where the emphasis on "a hand-up instead of a hand-out" is suggestive of the qualified egalitarianism of this position). We may summarize these correspondences as follows: 206 TABLE 4.--Summary of Correspondences Between Cleavages From Voting Records and Cleavages From the Theoretical Model. Cleavages Prom Voting Records Cleavages Cleavages From Theoretical Model: Number Included in Set Categories Separated By 1t 1 labor (main). social security (rightward). Left-Progressive vs. Right New Deal food stamps (righward). education (right- ward), housing (rightward), etc. 2 AFDC. food stamps (leftward), rent (left- Great Society vs. New Deal ward). GEO (leftward), etc. liberal Liberal 3 social security (leftward). general Left (Democratic) Right (Republi- spending (leftward). economic development. Great Society and vs. can) Great public works (leftward). 1977 social Left (Democratic) Society and security formula and 1971 and 1978 New Deal Liberals Right (Republi- corporate tax can) New Deal Liberal 4 wage-price controls. rationing. etc. Left and Right Left and Right Great Society: vs. Great Society: Statist Anti-Statist left and Right vs. Left and Right New Deal Statist New Deal: Anti- Statist Left-Progressive vs. Left-Progressive Statist (Left- Anti-Statist Corporate liberal) Right-Progessive: vs. Classical Liberal Statist (Right- (Conservative) and Corporate Liberal) Right-Progres- sive: Anti- Statist 5 Nat. Consumer Co-operative Bank. 050 Left Progressive vs. Classical Liberal (rightward). etc. (Statist and Anti- Statist) (Conservative) and Right Progressive: (Statist and Anti- Statist) 207 Groups Produced Dy the Cleavages, and Their Correspondences to Categories From the Theoretical Model If this apparent correspondence between the cleavages of the model and those suggested by the voting records is genuine, then it follows that the various groups into which the Senators are separated by the cleavages derived from the voting records should correspond to the categories of the model. The groups of Senators that are produced by these cleavages, and their correspondences with the categories in the model are as follows: TABLE 5.--Groups Produced By Cleavages From the Voting Records and Their Correspondences With the Categories of the Theore- tical Model. Stands on Category From Model Cleavages to Which Group Cor— Group 1 2 3 4 5 responds Members of Group l C C C C C Classical Liberal (Conservative and Right Progressive Anti-Statist) 2 C C C L C Right Progressive: Statist 3 C C C C L Left Progressive: Anti-Statist 4 C C C L L Left Progressive: Statist S L C C C L Right (Republican) New Deal: Anti- Statist Most conservative Repub- licans such as Goldwater, Curtis and Garn, plus conservative Northern Democrats Zorinsky and Lausche A few conservative Republicans, such as Roth A few conservative Republicans, such as Dole and Domenici A few conservative Republicans, such as Baker Some liberal Republicans such as Fong and Aiken 208 Stands on Category From Model Cleavages to Which Group Cor- Group 2 3 4 5 responds Members of Group 6 C C L L Right (Republican) A few liberal Republicans, New Deal: Statist such as Taft and Beall Jr. 7 L C C L Right (Republican) A few liberal Republicans, Great Society: such as Hatfield Anti-Statist 8 L C L L Right (Republican) Some, if not most, lib— Great Society: eral Republicans, such Statist as Weicker, Mathias and Javits 9 C L C L Left (Democratic) 0f doubtful existence, New Deal: Anti- but may include a few Statist liberal Democrats such as Harris and Montoya 10 C L L L Left (Democratic) Some liberal Democrats New Deal: Statist such as Robert Byrd, Cannon and Bible 11 L L C L Left (Democratic) Some liberal Democrats, Great Society: such as McGovern Anti-Statist 12 L L L L Left (Democratic) Most liberal Democrats, Great Society: Statist such as Humphrey, the Kennedys and Jackson Several other conceivable groups are not listed here, having a doubtful existence due to the way the cleavages tend to scale. Cleavages one, five and three tend to scale, in that order; cleavages one, five and two tend to scale, in that order. Such deviations from these scales are so few (or so partial) that they may be ignored for now. 209 Several of the listed groups are very minor. Group 7 is an anti-statist variant of Group 8, Group 6 is a statist variant of Group 5, and Group 9 (if it exists at all) is an anti-statist variant of Group 10. These are are all so small, and so little different from their larger relatives, that they can be largely ignored as separate groups hereafter. Most of what is said about their respec- tive larger relatives will probably apply to them. Groups 2, 3, 4 and 11 are small groups of uncertain boundaries and memberships (especially 11), but they are interesting and impor- tant groups, especially 2, 3 and 4, which seem to represent groups which were larger and more important in the past. It may be noticed that the position of the Southern Senators have not yet been mentioned much. These will be dealt with later. We may now review the main groups in more detail. Group 1 (Classical Liberals or Conservatives), includes conservative Republicans Goldwater, Curtis, Simpson, Tower, Hickenlooper, Butler (Md.), Buckley, Laxalt, Garn, Hatch, Helms, Fannin, Williams (Del.), Schoeppel, Mundt, Hruska, Dworshak, Bartlett (Oklagh Hansen, Bridges, Capehart, Schmitt, wallop and Brock, and usually conservative Republicans Thurmond, Scott (Va.), Cotton, Dominick, Bennett, Gurney, Jordan (Id.), Murphy, McClure, Lugar, Dirksen, Hayakawa, Carlson, Allott, and Morton, and conservative Northern Democrats Lausche and Zorinsky. The history of this group before the New Deal is difficult to trace, if it was even one, self- conscious group, but roughly it seems to have composed the 210 "conservative" (as opposed to "progressive" and "corporate liberal") elements in both major parties then. With the coming of the New Deal, we may identify it with those opposed to the New Deal from the beginning. Later, it seems to have constituted the Taft-Goldwater wing of the Republican party (and perhaps, later, the Reagan wing as well, although Gerald Ford had been a moderate or borderline member of the group, too). The members of this group outside the South have been over- whelmingly Republican since the end of the New Deal and, as will be seen, the "conservative" Southern Democrats do not really fit here. Its headquarters was in the East before the New Deal, but moved to the Midwesttnrthe time it was over. Since, the 19503, it has moved increasingly toward the West and, to a lesser extent, the South ("the Sunbelt" regions). Group 2 (Right-Progressive Statists, or Right—Corporate Liberals), probably includes Roth, and perhaps Danforth and Griffin. This group constituted the less egalitarian wing of the corporate liberals in the Progressive Era. Perhaps the candidacy of Leonard Wood in 1920 best represents it. Later, this group supported the early New Deal, but was alienated by its leftward moves in 1935 and later. Probably mostly Republican (in the North) by the end of the New Deal, some of the more rightist of the Dewey-Eisenhower "liberal" Republicans belong in this group. John Connally would seem to represent this group today, but not being a Senator, it is hard to know which Senators he resembles most. Most of the members today are probably Republicans of a "conservative" reputation. 211 In the Progressive Era, this group was probably strongest in the East and in urban areas, but as labor influence grew in the cities (and they moved left) this group probably transferred its base to the suburbs, and later toward the Sunbelt (although they are not as plentiful among Senators there as the prominence of people such as Connally might suggest). Group 3 and Group 4 (the Left-Progressive, Anti-Statist and Statist branches, respectively) probably include Dole, Domenici, Young (N.Dak.) and Hayakawa, and sometimes others (Group 3); and Baker and sometimes Griffin and others (Group 4). These groups probably constituted the main body of left and center "progressives" in the Progressive Era. Their more radical members (LaFollette, Bryan and the like) are better known than their moderate members, but the latter may have been more common, and were probably more what Hofstadter had in mind when he described the progressives. Probably most would be anti—statist by today's standards; Hoover was a good example of this. Statist ones were nonetheless probably found as well. After 1937, these groups were increasingly alienated from the New Deal, and most of their members (in the North) probably became Republican, as many already were. Most of the "progressives" eventually came to be seen as conservatives, as they generally are today. In the present, as in the past, their strongholds (or at least those of the anti-statist branch) seem to be in non-metropoli- tan areas, especially in the western Midwest and the West. 212 It seems also that a large portion of the Dewey-Eisenhower wing of the Republican party belongs in the more statist of these groups. This largely urban group, concentrated in the East and eastern Midwest, seems to share this intermediate position on the equality dimension with the older progressive Republicans, and to differ with most of them, and with the conservatives, mainly in being more statist. Group 5 (Right-New Deal Anti-Statists) and Group 6 (Right- Great Society Anti-Statists) are composed of liberal Republicans. The former group probably consists of Fong, Boggs, Smith, Aiken, Saxbe, Packwood, Cook, and often, Kuchel, Cooper, Prouty, Beall Sr. and Scott (Pa.): in their later years, Pearson, and, sometimes, Bellmon, voted with this group. The latter group consists of Weicker, Staf- ford, Mathias, Javits, Brooke, Case, Goodell, Schweiker (in his early days) and usually Percy, Prouty, Hatfield, Scott (Pa.), Cooper and Stevens (in his early days). Both of these groups were probably part of the Wilkie-Dewey-Eisenhower wing of the Republican party in the 19405 and 19505, but seemed to grow dissatisfied with Eisenhower, during his presidency, as being insufficiently liberal. They seem generally to have supported Rockefeller in his quest for the presi- dency. It seems that the differences between the two groups did not become noticeable until after the 1966 elections, when newer liberal Republicans, mostly from Group 6, began to enter the Senate. The difference was usually not obvious, and seems to have been increas- ingly obscured as the country has moved to the right. These groups, 213 especially the second, were mainly headquartered in urban areas, especially in the East and eastern Midwest. Group 10 and Group 12 are both composed of liberal Democrats. Group 10 (the Left-New Deal:Statist category) includes Byrd (W.Va.), Bible, and Cannon, sometimes Anderson (N.Mex.), Kerr, Monroney, Hayden, Harris, Montoya, Randolph, Symington, Long (Mo.), Fulbright, Smathers, Gore and Mansfield. Also, Southerners such as Long (La.), Sparkman and Johnston (S.C.) and sometimes Ellender and Hill, seem to belong here. Moynihan would seem to belong here on the basis of his repu- tation as a one-time liberal alienated by the policies of the late Johnson years, but his voting record is too short to confirm this. Group 12 (the Left-Great Society: Statist category) is composed of Hart (Mich.), Clark (Pa.), Culver, E. Kennedy (Mass.), Sarbanes, Humphrey, Mondale, Metzenbaum, Tydings, Kennedy (N.Y.), Muskie, Hathaway, Engle, Brewster, Hughes, McCarthy, Stevenson, Glenn, Pell, Pastore, Williams, Inouye, Matsunaga, Jackson, Magnuson, Moss, McGee, Riegle, Haskell, and Metcalf, (usually) Douglas, MacNamara, Young (Ohio), Neuberger, Morse, Carroll, McGee, Bartlett (Alas.), Burdick, Dodd, Mansfield, Biden, Leahy, McIntyre, Durkin, Harris, Clark (Ia.), Montoya, Nelson, Cranston, Abourezk, Hart (Col.), Symington, Long (Mo.), Randolph, Montoya, Anderson (N.Mex.), Hayden, Kerr, Gore, Fulbright, and Smathers, and sometimes Tunney, McGovern, Eagleton, Gravel, Hartke, and Church. These two groups, together with the two liberal Republican groups mentioned above, constituted the main support for Roosevelt's 214 New Deal after 1937 and for later liberal programs, although the Republican groups were somewhat more frugal and tolerant of corpora- tions in the area of taxes. These groups did not generally come apart until the 19603, as was the case with the two liberal Republi- can groups, and usually came apart over similar issues--most1y wel- fare and welfare—related issues. Members of Group 10 were generally less urban and more apt to be found in the western, southern, and border states than the mainly urban members of Group 12. Those members of the electorate who would probably fall into Group 10 were often alienated from the Democrats in the Johnson era, going for Wallace and, to lesser extent, Nixon in 1968, and for Nixon in 1972. Most of the "neo-conservatives" probably belong here. By the late 1970s, the differences between groups 10 and 12, as was the case with the differences between Groups 5 and 8, began to be submerged as the country moved to the right. The last group to be considered, Group 11 (the Left-Great Society: Anti-Statist category) is composed of liberal Democrats. Church, Hartke, Gravel, Eagleton, McGovern and Tunney should be placed here, while Abourezk, Hart (Colo), Nelson, Cranston, Clark (Ia.), Montoya, and Harris often approach this position, and Douglas, McNamara, Young (Ohio), Neuberger, Morse, Carroll, McGee, Bartlett (Alsk.) and Burdick have been known to. The history of this group is typically liberal Democratic, as is its behavior in most economic issues. 215 A Special Problem: The Place of the Southern Democrats Now we may consider what to do with the Southern Democrats. As has been said, some (Yarborough, Kefauver, Harris, Gore, Fulbright, Smathers, Monroney and Kerr) voted much like Northern liberal Democrats. Yarborough and Kefauver would fit very well into Group 12, and Gore and Harris would fit almost as well. E Fulbright,auuiSmathers would diverge somewhat in the direction of Group 10, and Monroney and Kerr would do more so. All except the first two Senators sometimes diverge from the liberals of Group 12 ; on labor issues. t Also included with the liberal Democrats in the survey sec- tion were Long (La.), Sparkman, Johnston (S.D.), Ellender and Hill. These generally, as has been said, seem to fit in with Group 10. In some ways they form a transition between the liberal group above and the more conservative Southerners to be described below. As a group, they tend to vote as follows: conservative on cleavage two, conservative on labor issues, and variable on other issues. Long, Sparkman and (as far as can be ascertained) Johnston tend further to be liberal on cleavage one, liberal or moderate on cleavage five, moderate to liberal on cleavage three, and moderate on cleavage four. Another group of Southern Democrats is the New South Democrats. They tend to fall between groups 10 and 12, usually being closer to 10, while they tend to be more conservative on labor issues than either. They might best be divided into two groups. The groups which is father to the left contains Bumpers, Ford and 216 Huddleston; the one to its right contains Bentsen, Stone, Chiles, Hollings, and Morgan, and, on its rightward edge, Nunn, and usually Johnston (La.). The two groups divide over a few issues, such as the Social Security vote of 1977. This tends to make the rightward group similar to Groups 6 and 5 (the Right-New Deal categories). Finally, we come to the Old Southerners. They are commonly seen as being very similar to the conservative Republicans on econo— mic issues (and, in fact, on most issues, except racial issues.) And it is true that the two groups tend to vote alike more often than not. However, in a large minority of cases, they diverge. These divergences consist mostly of those over social security (the rightward one), public works and public works jobs (the rightward ones), and school lunches in 1970, and passage of the 1969 tax bill-- and certain other taxes (the 1969 surtax extension and the 1977 tax cut). Most of these relate to the sixth or seventh set of cleavages. As was discussed above, the sixth set of cleavages most clearly represents a conservative Republicans-versus-Old Southerners cleavage as the seventh set tends to cut across the groups. It is in any case clear that the Old Southerners are a separate group from the conser- vative Republicans, who mostly belong to the Classical Liberal category (though not exclusively--remember Roth, etc.). The ques- tion now is one of where Old Southerners are to be placed. They are clearly more statist, overall, then Classical Liberals, as their position on the issues of set six indicate. They are to the right of the other cleavages on the scale--those of sets one, two, three and 217 five——for the most part. So they seem to be inegalitarian and statist. Yet they differ from such inegalitarian statists as Roth on most cleavages of set six. A possible explanation of their position, which is somewhat bizarre, yet is in accord with many of the historical facts, is that their "leftist" position on set six actually shows them to be the right of (more inegalitarian than) the classical liberals. This assumes the truth of the theory suggested in the first part of this work, which described the theoretical model being tested--namely, that the old-style Southerners are really traditionalist conserva— tives. If this is true, then their embracing of seemingly leftist propositions is not unusual: it is parallelled by the behavior of Disraeli and Bismarck. Whether this is the result of a desire to hinder an economic and political rival (Northern business), or a feeling of pure spite for their bourgeois social rivals or a pater— nalistic attitude twoard the lower classes, or a feeling that the burdens of the programs on question will not fall very much on their own shoulders (being carried partly by the beneficiaries, in the case of certain "social insurance" programs, and/or partly by the bourgeois businessmen), or some combinations of these motives is unclear, but it is not vital for the purposes of this work to deter- mine which. Suffice it to say that the Traditionalist Right and the Socialist Left have often joined hands against the Classical Liberal Center. 218 This interpretation of the Old South Democrats would not be likely to be accepted by those who see the South as part of a bour- geois liberal American consensus, among others. Another interpre- tation of their behavior is that it is slightly populistic, in the sense of being an indication of agrarian and petit-bourgeois dislike of Northern big business. This sentiment was once regarded as leftist, but with leftward drift of the political center in this century it now seems moderately conservative. This theory, however, seems weak, in view of the strong conservatism of this group on some economic issues--on some legal services votes and on the 1968 HUD vote, for example, more conservative Republicans take the liberal position than do Old South Democrats; and in view of what Kousser and others have to say about the success and future extent of Populism in the South after the 18903. More plausible is a variant of this view, which says that the behavior of the Old South Democrats represents a regional reaction of local big businessmen and big farmers, as well as small businessmen and small farmers, to the threat of domination by out- siders (i.e. Northern big businessmen). It is thus a case of rela- tively conservative forces adopting leftdwing tools. This practice seems to be common in the so-called Third World, among "conserva- tives" who defend the positions of local elites, internally, while joining the Left in trying to restrain American influence. This explanation of Old South Democrat behavior is the safest and most conservative. 219 There is some variety within the Old Southern group. Talmadge, and to a lesser extent, Ervin and Jordan, are the most liberal, at least in the sense of being egalitarian. Housing, education and the establishment of the CEO are issues over which they have been known to diverge from the rest. The most anti-statist and also the most like the Republicans are the Harry Byrds and Robertson. Frequently allied with them were Allen, or Ervin and Jordan, or Russell or Holland (in different circumstances). The issues on this dimension which most divided the group were ordinary public works, the Labor- HEW funds vote of 1976, wage-price controls and rationing. Eastland, Stennis and, to a lesser extent, McClellan, are relatively statist and relatively inegalitarian. Cleavage Sets From the Voting Records Which Do Not Correspond to Cleavages From the Model A number of the sets of cleavages mentioned above (the sixth through the thirteenth) do not clearly correspond to the major cleavages of the model. We may now consider how some of these may be fitted in and what their historical significance may be. The sixth and seventh sets of cleavages seem to involve the liberty dimension more than the equality dimension, which makes them seek like the fourth set of cleavages but unlike the first, second, third and fifth sets. This is said for two reasons. One is because the proposals involved seem less clearly egalitarian than most of those involved in the other sets of cleavages--public works and general social security increases as opposed to labor proposals, 220 food stamps, AFDC, anti-poverty measures and low-income housing. The second reason is that these cleavages do somewhat parallel those in set four (wage—price controls, rationing, etc.) Many of those who are "liberal" on the cleavages of set four while being "conser- vative on the others (of sets one, two, three and five) are "liberal" on these cleavages of sets six and seven. These include a few conservative Republicans such as Roth and most Old Southerners. The cleavages of set seven (ordinary public works and Labor- HEW funds in 1976) seem to be to the "right", or better, "above" those of set four (if the liberty dimension is seen as being verti- cal, with libertarianism at the top and statism at the bottom) in regard to the Republicans, as various of them (such as Young of North Dakota, Dole, Baker, Griffin, Roth and Domenici) seem to be below at least some of these cleavages, but above those of set four. (Things are different regarding the relationship of the cleavages among Old Southerners: the cleavages of set seven are even with or below those of set four.) Insofar as the seventh and fourth sets of cleavages tend to scale in this way, they might be identified with some of the historical steps on the road to statism. The seventh set (ordinary public works and Labor-HEW funds) may be the one to really repre- sent the main cleavages between those who have accepted the lasting changes wrought by the New Deal and those who have not, insofar as these involved broadly-directed government spending, especially that on public works and social security. In both the seventh set 221 and the New Deal cleavages, opposition to these things came from conservative Republicans and a few Democrats, mostly Southern (including Harry Byrd, Sr.), while almost everyone else supported them. Besides public works and the programs under Social Security act, other things brought by the New Deal include labor legislation, various measures (such as attempts to provide public control of water power through the TVA) to help people break away from excessive dependence on big business, and (after 1935) a less tolerant anti- trust policy toward business. The first two of these involve the equality dimension more than the liberty dimension and the issue of statism. The third, antitrust, would seem to do even more; however, our examination of the Progressive Era showed that business often supports or comes to support government regulation. And the revision of the antitrust law of 1976 (which generally tightened the restric— tiveness of the law) got the support of some Senators with otherwise quite inegalitarian voting records (e.g. Roth and Harry Byrd Jr.): indeed, it is very similar in its cleavages to the issues of the seventh set of cleavages, differing mainly in that most Old South- erners opposed it. This proposal would seem, then, to represent something like the stand of the more aggressive (but not necessarily egalitarian) regulationists. And so it seems to roughly fit in with set seven, and confirm its status as a New Deal-versus-anti- New Deal cleavage. The fourth set of cleavages (rationing, wage-price controls, etc.) may have its own historical implications. During the New 222 Deal, even in its early days, "progressive" Republicans (as described by Feinman) seem to have feared Franklin Roosevelt's statist tenden- cies, particularly his tendency to strengthen the executive and the bureaucracy, and to support concentration of power in the state as in business. Similarly, "Modern Republicans" of the 19408 and 19508 often joined their conservative fellow partisans in denouncing the New Deal 5 tendency toward government economic planning. Usually, this meant Keynesian deficit spending, rationing and wage-price controls (at least in peacetime), and any proposal for more explicit government direction of the economy. In our vote list, we have no good examples of the last, nor of votes on deficits per se. There are votes on public works jobs, which are intended as Keynesian economic stimulus, but these belong in the sixth set of cleavages. This leaves rationing and wage-price controls. These do belong in the fourth set of cleavages, and were often denounced by Modern Republicans (although Eisenhower accepted stand-by wage-price control and authority), and involve a strong executive and bureaucracy, and concentration of power, which most progressive Republicans disliked. Our fourth set of cleavages, therefore, may represent this histori- cal cleavage. The seventh and fourth sets of cleavages thus seem to cor- respond to the two cleavages on the liberty dimension indicated in Figure 26. The cleavages of set seven would correspond to those separating the Conservative category and that with Hoover in it from those with Dewey, Eisenhower, Wilson, Al Smith, Theodore Roosevelt, 223 Hamilton and John Connally in them. The cleavages of set four would correspond to that separating the Conservative category and those with Dewey, Eisenhower, Wilson and Al Smith in them from those with Theodore Roosevelt, Hamilton and Connally in them. Those in between the two cleavages (the likes of Dewey, Eisenhower, Wilson and Al Smith) would seem to be the sort of people who can tolerate a large quantity of "big government" (in terms of legislation, spend- ing and/or taxes), while still being quite fearful that government will get too powerful. The cleavages of set six (social security, public works jobs, school lunches in 1975 and the 1969 tax bill) are somewhat different from those of set seven. Conservative Republicans, including even some, such as Roth, who were below the sixth set, tend to be united in being above or to the right of the seventh set of cleavages, while Old Southerners, including some, such as Harry Byrd, Jr., who were above the seventh set of cleavages, tend to be united in being below the cleavages in the sixth set, as are most other Democrats, and most liberal Republicans. While set seven resembles set four considerably--both of them putting most Republicans in opposition to many if not most Old Southerners--set seven tends to unite the conservative Republicans and Old Southerners internally while divid- ing them from each other, whereas set six tends (as set four does) to cut across the boundaries between the conservative Republicans and Old Southerners. Moreover, set six tends to join Old Southerners ——who have reputations of being as conservative, or even more 224 conservative, than the conservative Republicans—dwith liberal Demo- crats and liberal Republicans. The implications of these findings will be discussed below, when the Old Southerners are discussed. Perhaps this divergence between these two "conservative" groups reflects some underlying Democratic versus Republican cleavage which gives the party differences real meaning. The cleavages of set eight seem to exemplify such a distinction more clearly. In general, it seems that, while cleavages over welfare-type and labor- type issues tend to cut across party lines, certain tax issues and certain spending programs of broad coverage (social security) or macroeconomic implication (public works) tend to correspond to party lines, in many cases. However, the evidence on this which is found in the data here does not warrant stressing this matter very strongly, and we will say little more of this. The cleavages of set nine and ten are of uncertain origin. They suggest the old Democratic-versus-Whig battles over internal improvements, which later become Democrat-versus—Republican battles. By the time of the Wilson Adminstration, however, even most Democrats seem to have come to accept spending on certain kinds of improve- ments (e.g. road building) and related aids to economic activity (e.g. loans to farmers). So it is not surprising that even most conservative Republicans today like to spend federal money on some domestic projects. In regard to some, such as certain hOSpital and education appropriations (cleavage set nine), they join the great majority of other Senators in supporting the projects. In regard 225 to others, such as aiding Lockheed, providing money for an SST, granting near-monopoly status to a private company in connection with the Communications Satellite, constructing certain water pro- jects without charging user fees, and sharing funds with local governments, most of those known as liberals have been known to oppose them, the liberals generally not favoring the groups being aided, and thus reverse the normal stands of the groups on federal domestic spending. This leads us to the eleventh set of cleavages. These seem to involve regional coalitions, and thus suggest that constituency interests are exercising an overriding effect on these. The twelfth set of cleavages may represent the division, which appeared in the 19608 among liberal Democrats, between upholders of the "consensus" politics of the 19508 and its various manifestations (including the latest version of corporate liberalism and, in non-economic matters, a bipartisan foreign policy), and their criticscnmthe left. This division appeared most prominently over the Vietnam War, but involved other issues. The thirteenth set of cleavages seems to separate from the main body of liberals those "liberal" Republicans who sometimes dragged their feet on various items of the liberal agenda in the Kennedy years, but then came to support them in the Johnson years (at least from 1965 on). Perhaps these cleavages represent the basis (along with the first set of cleavages) for setting-up a category of truly moderate Republicans (opposed to merely moderately liberal 226 Republicans) between the right and left wings of the party, but the evidence does not yet seem to warrant a clear decision in favor of doing this. 227 ENDNOTES 1A step by step description of a procedure used in making an analysis similar to that done here, showing how issues cleavages may be aggregated and then used to create groups into which indi- viduals may be placed is providedzhnHarold J. Spaeth's Supreme Court PolicyiMaking: Explanation and Prediction (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman and Company, 1979), especially on pp. 128-137. 21h addition to prior study and preliminary examination of the records, some ideas for the arrangement of names were obtained from Michael Foley's The New Climate: Liberal Influence on a Con- servative Institution 1959-1972 (New Haven: Yale university Press, 1972), particularly the voting tables in the back of the book. CHAPTER IV CONCLUSION Our examination of the evidence has generally confirmed the existence and importance of the cleavages and groups in the model, and supplied us with additional information. The existence of a liberty dimension was confirmed, as was the existence of the various cleavages from the model: the Progres- sive (and conservative)-ver8us-New Deal, or Conservative-Liberal cleavage (identified with the first set of cleavages); the New Deal liberal (and conservative)-versus-Great Society liberal cleavage (identified with the second set of cleavages); the Republican and Old Southern-versus-liberal Democrat cleavage (identified with the third set of cleavages); the relatively statist-versus—relatively anti-statist cleavage (identified with the fourth set of cleavage) and the Left Progressive-versus-Right Progressive (and conservative) cleavage (identified with the fifth set of cleavages). Other cleavages were also found. Some contrast between conservative Republicans and Old Southerners had been expected, but not so great a one as was found. And the frequency with which the Old Southerners voted with the liberal Democrats was greater than what was expected. Also, the practice of liberal and conservative Republicans joining forces against these two wings of the Democrats, which occurred on several occasions, was not expected. 228 229 The other cleavage of major interest that was found was another one along the liberty dimension, which seems to be related to New Deal issues, particularly on public works. This allows a refinement of the liberty dimension, which was nonetheless implied in the description of the model. The work which has been done in this thesis has helped to shed light on a number of problems in American political history: (1) Progressives in the New Deal era. The "progressives" are commonly seen as the "(modern) liberals" (in the conventional sense) of the Progressive Era. Yet many of them opposed the New Deal, a supposedly "liberal" program. Some see this opposition as the result of frustrated ambition or the possession of prickly or uncooperative dispositions on the part of individual progressives. However, we should consider the possibility that their opposition arose from ideological differences with the New Deal. This need not mean that they were really "conservative", in the Progressive- Era sense, but rather that they were somewhere in between these conservatives and the New Dealers. In other words, they wished to move the country to the left of where it was, but only so far left, and the New Deal went beyond this point. The situation seem to be clarified considerably if concepts from this paper's model are used, especially the Left-Progressive and New Deal categories, as con- trasted with each other, and the liberty dimension, as contrasted with the equality dimension. 230 (2) New Deal and Great Society liberals. The 19608 saw many formerly loyal supporters of the New Deal liberal Democratic coalition desert the party, in apparent opposition to the policies of the Great Society. George Wallace (in 1968) and Richard Nixon (in 1968 and 1972) seem to have won the support of many of these voters. What was the nature of their disagreement with the liberal leaders? As in the case of the progressives in the New Deal, we seem to have the case of people who wanted to move the country left at one time, but only so far left; now the political situation in the country had gone beyond that point, and they were now on the right. (3) The Progressive Era itself. The ideological complexity of this era, above and beyond personality conflicts, seems to be well- recognized. In particular, the nature of "corporate liberalism" needs to be determined more precisely. Is it merely liberalism as advocated by the corporations, or a special, moderate kind of liberalism, or something neither wholly liberal nor wholly conserva- tive? There is a need for concepts from this work--the contrasts between the equality and liberty dimensions, between Right and Left Progressivism, between radical and moderate Left Progressives, etc., and there seems to be room for considerable further analysis of this kind. (4) The ideological position of Herbert Hoover. This man's philosophy was clearly quite complex, as he was a man of many contrasts--individualist yet regulatory technocrat, quasi-corporatist 231 yet would-be trust-buster, foe of socialism and the New Deal yet advocate of soak-the-rich tax policies. Clearly there is a need for concepts used in this paper-—particularly the category of moderately Left-Progressive Anti-Statists, into which he seems to fit. (5) The stages of the New Deal. The fact that Franklin Roosevelt lost some of his supporters with every step of the New Deal should, in itself, lead people to realize that a scale of attitudes needs to be applied to this situation. The Anti-statist/ Statist, Right-Progressive[Left-Progressive and Left Progressive/ New Deal dichotomies are needed here. (6) The conservative—liberal conflict within the post-New Deal Republican party. The fact that ”liberal Republican" Dwight Eisenhower was not particularly close ideologically to "liberal Republicans" such as Jacob Javits shows us the need to discriminate more finely among Republicans than we do by merely dividing them into conservative and liberal wings. This suggests that there should be a scale of attitudes for this situation, with conservative Republicans, Eisenhower type "Modern Republicans" and more clearly liberal Republicans such as Javits distinguished from each other. There are many other area where the sort of analysis done in this paper would be useful: (1) Conservatism in the Progressive Era. This is a little— studied subject. Therefore it is not very surprising that there is not a clear definition of it, or even a reasonable enumeration of who these "conservatives" were. So-called conservatives such as 232 President Taft considered themselves progressives and certainly supported much progressive legislation; the latter can also be said about people such as Henry Cabot Lodge, Sr. As to people such as Joseph Cannon, who thought that Taft was too far to the left, their voting records are not well-known: it would be interesting to see how much progressive legislation they turn out to have voted for. So it is clear that much work remains to be done here, and some general conceptual clarification and definition would be helpful even with- out (or as preparation for) the conducting of in-depth studies of them, such as those of their voting records. (2) Democrats before the New Deal. It is often said that the Democrats were often quite conservative before the New Deal. Yet here, too, "conservatism" needs to be defined. "Conservative" Al Smith, for example, supported much "social insurance" and labor legislation of the type enacted in the New Deal (of which he was so critical). Again, we see a lack of the sense of the often rela- tive nature of the terms "conservative" and "liberal" (and "right" and "left"). (3) The ideological position of Coolidge, Harding and their supporters in the 19208. They are called "conservatives", usually in contrast to being "progressives"--yet they repealed very little Progressive Era legislation. Some say that they used existing regulations and commissions to help business rather than to restrain it--but this is nothing new to modern students of the Progressive Era. It is simply "corporate liberalism"--and it must be remembered 233 that "corporate liberals" are "liberal" in some sense, and so a simple labeling of them as conservatives is not enough. (4) wendell Wilkie and Thomas Dewey. The two are often classed together as "moderate" or "liberal", "internationalist" opponents of Robert Taft. Yet it also has been argued that Wilkie was more liberal than Dewey-ébut was he? This is a matter which should be settled, if only because it may relate to later cleavages among moderate-to—liberal Rebpublicans. (5) The "neo-conservatives". This term refers to various people, such as Daniel P. Moynihan, who had once been regarded (by themselves and others) as liberal and were not often in opposition to other liberals, and were sometimes called conservatives, even though they generally claimed not to have changed. Their deviation from mainstream liberalism has been attributed by some to personality factors, as was the opposition of many progressives to the New Deal. As in the previous case, we recommend considering an ideological explanation. It seems that these "neo-conservatives" probably fit in the category of New Deal liberals alienated by the Great Society, described above. (6) The Reagan-Ford battle for the Republican Presidential nomination in 1976. Was this a revival of the Taft-Willkie, Taft— Dewey and Taft-Eisenhower battles of earlier decades? Or was it an internal struggle within the Taft-Goldwater wing of the Republican party? It would also be interesting to know to what extent this cleavage was a revival of much earlier cleavages that had become 234 suppressed as politics had moved left, causing these groups to put aside their quarrels in the face of a greater enemy to the left. (7) We should ascertain for certain whether the "supply-side" versus "monetarist" conflict among conservatives in recent years represents the same as cleavage as the Reagan-Ford conflict. (8) The ideological positions of Richard Nixon and Jimmy Carter. That they are difficult to determine seems to be widely accepted, so few will dispute that they need further examination. (9) The ideology of Southern politicians. There are still many disputes about the South to be settled, as has already been indicated. However, in addition, we have discovered a surprising amount of economic liberalism in such supposedly ultraconservative Senators as Eastland and Stennis, which provides another puzzle to solve. This sort of study can be extended still further, to various non-economic issue areas (foreign affairs; racial issues, crime and other "social issues"; etc.). The field of classification in those areas is at about the level of development as it is in the area of economic issues: typologies with only two, three or four categories and only one dimension is about as much as is generally achieved in these areas. Then, of course, one may try to integrate these typo- logies in those areas with each other and with those in the economic area. This seldom gets beyond a four-category, two-dimensionsl classification, based on conservative-liberal dichotomies in 235 the areas of economics and foreign affairs, or economics and social issues. Furthermore, we may hope that ideological classifications may be extended to other countries. A sort of beginning of this was included in the action on the theoretical model, when American and European politics were compared. A wider spectrum may be expected in European politics, and perhaps greater complexity in terms of the number of dimensions (e.g. the inclusion of an explicitly religious dimension); on the other hand, some reduction in dimensions may be possible (e.g. antitrust issues seem to be of relatively little importance in Europe). BIBLIOGRAPHY BIBLIOGRAPHY Americans for Constitutional Action. ACA Index 1963-1978 (ACA: Washington, D.C., 1963-1978). AFL—CIO Labor Looks at Congress. (Washington: AFL-CIO, 1959-1978). Anderson, Lee F., Meredith W. Watts, Jr. and Allen R. Wilcox. Legislative Roll-Call Analysis. (Evanston: Northwestern University Press, 1966). Barone, Michael, Grant Ujifusa and Douglas Matthews. The Almanac of American Politics 1972—1980. (New York: E. P. Dutton and Company, 1972-1980). Bartley, Numan V. and Hugh D. Graham. Southern Politics and the Second Reconstruction. (Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press, 1975). Burnham, Walter Dean. Critical Elections and the Mainsprings of American Politics. (New York: W. W. Norton, 1970). Campbell, Angus, Philip E. Converse, Warren E. Miller and Donald E. Stokes. The American Voter. (Chicago: university of Chicago Press, 1960). Congressional Quarterly Almanac 1959-1978. (Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quartely, Inc., 1959-1978). Crane, Wilder, Jr. "A Caveat of Roll-Call Studies of Party Voting". Midwest Journal of Political Science 4 (August. 1960). Erickson, Robert S. and Norman R. Luttbeg. American Public Opinion: Its Origins, Content and Impact. (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1973). Farris, Charles D. "A Method of Determining Ideological Groupings in Congress". Journal of Politics 20 (May, 1958), 308-388. Feinman, Ronald L. Twilight of Progressivism: The Western Republi- can Senators and the New Deal. (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1981). Foley, Michael. The New Senate: Liberal Influence on a Conserva- tive Institution 1959-1972. (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1972). 237 238 Graham, Otis, L., Jr. Encore for Reform. (New York: Oxford Univer- sity Press, 1967). Grantham, Dewey W. Jr. The Democratic South. (Athens, Georgia: The university Press, 1963). Greenstein, Fred I. and Elton F. Jackson. "A Second Look at the Validity of Roll-Call Analysis". Midwest Journal of Politi- cal Science 7 (May, 1963), 156-166. Hartz, Louis. The Liberal Tradition in America: An Interpretation of American Political Thought Since the Revolution. (New York: Harcourt, Brace and World, 1955). Hayek, Friedrich A. "Why I Am Not a Conservative" in Hayek's The ' Constitution of Liberty. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1960). Hofstadter, Richard A. The Age of Reform: From Bryan to F.D.R. (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1955). Holt, James. Egngressional Insurgents and the Party System 1909- 1916. (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1967). Kirk, Russell. "Conservatism" in the Encyclgpedia Britannica. (Chicago: Encyclopedia Britannica, Inc., 1960). Kolko, Gabriel. The Triumph of Conservatism: A reinterpretation of American History, 1900-1916. (New York: Macmillan, 1963). Kousser, J. Morgan. The Shaping of Southern Politics: Suffrage Restriction and the Establishment of the One-Party South, 1880—1910. (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1974). Larson, Arthur. What We Are For. (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1959). Levitan, Sar A. and Robert Taggart. The Promise of Greatness. (Cambridge: Harvard university Press, 1976). Link, Arthur S. Woodrow Wilson and the Progressive Era 1910-1917. (New York: Harper and Row, 1954). Ladd, Everett Carl, with Charles D. Hadley. Transformations of the 'American Party System: Political Coalitions from the New “Deal to the 19708. (New York: W. W. Norton, 1958). MacRae, Duncan Jr. "A Method for Identifying Issues and Factions from Legislative Votes." American Political Science Review 59 (December, 1965), 909-926. 239 . "Some Underlying Variables in Legislative Roll- Call Votes". Public Opinion Quarterly 18 (Summen.l954), 191-195. MacRae, Duncan and Susan Borker Schwarz. "Identifying Congressional Issues by Multidimensional Models." Midwest Journal of Poli- tical Science 12 (May, 1968), 181-201. Patterson, James J. Congressional Conservatives and the New Deal: the Growth of the Conservative Coalition in Congress, 1933- 1939. (Lexington: University of Kentucky Press, 1967). Phillips, Kevin P. The Emerging Republican Majority. (New York: Garden City, 1969). Reichard, Gary. The Reaffirmation of Republicanism: Eisenhower and the Eighry-Third Congress. (Knoxville: the University of Tennessee Press, 1975). Reichley, A. James. Conservatives in anfiAge of Change: The Nixon and Ford Administrations. (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institute, 1981). Riker, William H. "A.Method for Determining the Significance of Roll—Calls in Voting Bodies", in John C. Wahlke and Heinz Eulau, Legislative Behavior: A Reader in Theory and Research. (Glencoe, 111.: The Free Press, 1959), pp. 377-387. Rossiter, Clinton. Conservatism in America: The Thankless Persus- '§$93, (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1955). . Parties and Politics in America. (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1960). Rusher, William A. The Making of the New Majoritngarty (Ottawa: Green Hill Publishers, 1975). Spaeth, Harold J. Supreme Court Poligy Making: Erplanation and Prediction. (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman and Company, 1979). Thelen, David P. Robert M. LaFollette and the Insurgent Spirit (Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1976). Truman, David B. The Congressional Party: A Case Study. (New York: John Wiley and Sons, Inc., 1959). Viereck, Peter. Conservatism.Revisited. (New York: Macmillan, 1960). 240 Weinstein, James A. The Corporate Ideal in the Liberal State 1900- 1918. (Boston: Beacon Press, 1968). Wilson, Joan Hoff. Herbert Hoover: Forgotten Progressive. (Boston: Little, Brown and Company, 1975). InWWW WI ' M 940