A: . if. . a... A i 3.9%. : ix. am... «3.. afimflifi. fififow 3.4,. 3% Jaguar}? . .v I l E , _. x . unuwua~a... 1:. tn. 3.... :«vs .3...“ It , .le. a...“ Cola—.9391“. H41. u -.,4V.u....s+....l AN STA Immuuiiiml \mijziigiiiimi 3 1293 01 LIBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled CAPITAL INVESTMENT BY RISK NEUTRAL AGENTS: MERGING ADJUSTMENT COSTS AND IRREVERSIBILITY presented by Hirokatsu Asano has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. Economics degree in Date May 10, 1999 MSU is an Affirmatiw Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0—12771 .— —v‘. . ._‘ r -.._ —-r——- v" v fir ‘-— ' v " PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINE return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 1198 c/CIRCJDmDmpGS-p.“ CAPITAL INVESTMENT BY RISK NEUTRAL AGENTS: MERGING ADJUSTMENT COSTS AND IRREVERSIBILITY By Hirokatsu Asano A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 1999 Current < firm mal capital i1 Optimal anal} 3i3 include3 Shows U the disc anal} Sis ABSTRACT CAPITAL INVESTMENT BY RISK NEUTRAL AGENTS: MERGING ADJUSTMENT COSTS AND IRREVERSIBILITY By Hirokatsu Asano Current capital investment affects future investment by setting conditions upon which a firm makes future investment decisions. This analysis applies option pricing theory to capital investment in order to determine possibilities of future investment, and shows the optimal investment choice for a firm contemplating future investment. The theoretical analysis develops a model for capital investment by risk neutral agents. The model includes costly reversibility and fixed costs of investment. Then, numerical analysis shows that optimal investment is approximately linear in economic parameters such as the discount rate. Empirical analysis shows that actual investment behaves as theoretical analysis predicts. \Vi been com; he gate m; and his CD! the Other H 010m. it CUmmmcc I m isl‘ficially and 3111(1) “Mk Fir grateful to achicVemr ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Without the help and support from many people, this dissertation could not have been completed. First, I would like to thank Professor Robert Rasche for guidance that he gave me throughout this work. An article that he suggested me initiated this research, and his comments and suggestions improved this work greatly. I would also like to thank the other members of my committee, Professors Jeffery Wooldridge and Gerhard Glomm, for their insight and support. I am truly thankful to all members of my committee for the quality and the speed of their feedback on my work. I am very fortunate to have good friends at Michigan State University. I especially want to thank Daiji, Heather, Hiroki, Katsushi and Pablo. They made my life and study in Lansing enjoyable, if not pleasant, and some of them also contributed to my work. Finally, I thank my parents for allowing me to pursue my Ph.D. dream. I am also grateful to my brother and his family for their support. They made my academic achievement possible. LIST 0 LIST 0 INTRO CHAP 0an b) I I.) TABLES OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ............................... vii LIST OF FIGURES ............................................................................................... ix INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................... 1 1. Irreversibility, Costly Reversibility and Fixed Costs of Investment ............. 2 2. Prior Work .................................................................................................... 4 CHAPTER 1 COSTLY REVERSIBLE INVESTMENT WITHOUT FIXED COSTS ................ 8 1—1. Bellman Equation ...................................................................................... 9 1-2. Optimal Investment for Costly Reversible Investment without Fixed Costs ............................................................................. 11 CHAPTER 2 COSTLY REVERSIBLE INVESTMENT WITH FIXED COSTS ....................... 18 2-1. Optimal Investment for Costly Reversible Investment with Fixed Costs .................................................................................. 19 2-2. User Cost of Capital ................................................................................ 23 CHAPTER 3 OPTIMAL INVESTMENT AND EFFECTS OF PARAMETERS ...................... 25 3-1. Optimal Investment Rule ......................................................................... 25 3-2. Effects of Parameters on Optimal Investment ......................................... 27 iv 'l ' “MM.- CHAP' ECOXI 44. $3. CHAPT IXDFSI 54. fit 54-8 CHAPTER 4 ECONOMETRIC PROCEDURE .......................................................................... 44 4-1. Econometric Model ................................................................................. 44 4-2. Analysis Methods .................................................................................... 47 i. Data Sources .......................................................................................... 47 ii. Procedure .............................................................................................. 48 CHAPTER 5 INDUSTRY ANALYSIS ....................................................................................... 52 5-1. Computer and Office Equipment Industry .............................................. 52 i. Estimation and Measure of Zero Investment ......................................... 52 ii. Test of Model Selection ........................................................................ 57 iii. Test of Serial Correlation .................................................................... 58 5-2. Automobile Industry ................................................................................ 58 i. Estimation and Measure of Zero Investment ......................................... 58 ii. Test of Model Selection ........................................................................ 63 iii. Test of Serial Correlation .................................................................... 63 5-3. Airline Industry ........................................................................................ 64 i. Estimation and Measure of Zero Investment ......................................... 64 ii. Test of Model Selection ........................................................................ 71 iii. Test of Serial Correlation .................................................................... 71 5-4. Summary .................................................................................................. 72 CONCLUSIONS .................................................................................................... 74 APPEXD IXVE A-l. APPEXDI AND E APPENDIX A. TWO PERIOD MODEL OF COSTLY REVERSIBLE INVESTMENT WITHOUT FIXED COSTS .................................................. 76 A-l. Investment Model ................................................................................... 77 A-2. Values of Future Investment and Disinvestment.... ................................ 79 A-3. Optimal Investment for First Period ....................................................... 80 APPENDIX B. APPROXIMATION OF G SATISFYING J(R,G) = O ................ 85 B-I. Approximation by Order of Exponents ................................................... 85 B-2. Approximation by Binomial Series ........................................................ 86 B-3. Refinement of Approximation ................................................................ 87 APPENDIX C. FUNCTION q WITH AND WITHOUT FIXED COSTS AND RANGE OF INACTION ........................................................................ 89 C-1. Coefficients of Function q, 8,. and 8,. ..................................................... 89 C-2. Range of Inaction .................................................................................... 90 APPENDIX D. SERIALLY CORRELATED ERROR ........................................ 91 D-l. Voung’s Test of Model Selection ........................................................... 91 D-2. Estimated p and Durbin-Watson Test of OLS Residuals ....................... 94 D-3. Discussion ............................................................................................... 95 APPENDIX E. TWO STEP ESTIMATION FOR LIMITED DEPENDENT VARIABLE MODEL ............................................ 96 BIBLIOGRAPHY ................................................................................................ 100 vi Iablel Rco Iable3.l (:3 Tahiti} Sit Iablc3.3 Cri Tablel-i (‘rj Tablefwj Tar Iabiefwb Tm: Ia‘nie3.7 Tar; Table 3.8 In LIST OF TABLES Table 1 Recent Literature on Adjustment Cost Function and Irreversibility ..................... 5 Table 3.1 Cases for Simulations ...................................................................................... 28 Table 3.2 Significance of Discount Rate ......................................................................... 32 Table 3.3 Critical Value for Investment without Fixed Costs, yi .................................. 33 Table 3.4 Critical Value for Disinvestment without Fixed Costs, y' ............................. 34 Table 3.5 Target Value for Investment with Fixed Costs, yL, ........................................ 35 Table 3.6 Trigger Value for Investment with Fixed Costs (Natural Logged), Ln y; ..... 36 Table 3.7 Target Value for Disinvestment with Fixed Costs, yi-u ................................... 37 Table 3.8 Trigger Value for Disinvestment with Fixed Costs, y}, ................................. 38 Table 3.9 Significance of Quadratic Terms and Interaction Terms ................................. 40 Table 3.10 Measure of Minimum Investment (Natural Logged), Ln G” ...................... 41 Table 3.11 Measure of Minimum Disinvestment (Natural Logged), Ln G‘ .................. 42 Table 3.12 Measure of Inaction Range (without Fixed Costs, Natural Logged), Ln G..43 Table 4.1 Investment Models and Econometric Methods ............................................... 49 vii Table-51 MC Table-33 1351 Iablei.3 MO 1:111:54 Scn’ Iablc55 MCZ Iablcib Iisti. Iablci] Mot“ IablcS.8 Scri; IablcS.9 Med IableSIO Est Table 5.11 M0 Table 5.12 Ser IEIIIIC DI L00 IableDl \Iod IabIeD.‘ 't' 31:". If? Table 5.1 Measure of Zero Investment (Computer and Office Equipment Industry) ...... 53 Table 5.2 Estimation of Computer and Office Equipment Industry ................................ 56 Table 5.3 Model Selection for Computer and Office Equipment Industry ...................... 57 Table 5.4 Serial Correlation Test for Computer and Office Equipment Industry ........... 58 Table 5.5 Measure of Zero Investment (Automobile Industry) ....................................... 59 Table 5.6 Estimation of Automobile Industry ................................................................. 62 Table 5.7 Model Selection for Automobile Industry ....................................................... 63 Table 5.8 Serial Correlation Test for Automobile Industry ............................................. 64 Table 5.9 Measure of Zero Investment (Airline Industry)............................ ................... 65 Table 5.10 Estimation of Airline Industry ....................................................................... 70 Table 5.11 Model Selection for Airline Industry ............................................................. 71 Table 5.12 Serial Correlation Test for Airline Industry ................................................... 72 Table D.l Log Likelihood of Investment Model ............................................................. 92 Table D2 Model Selection under Serially Correlated Error ........................................... 93 Table D3 Estimated Coefficient of AR(1) Process, p ..................................................... 94 Table D4 Durbin-Watson Statistic for OLS Residuals ................................................... 94 viii Figure 1.1 Figure 1.3 Figure 1.3 figure 1.4 HSure 2.1 FiSure 2.2 n,- (11 O 0 Figure 1.1 Figure 1.2 Figure 1.3 Figure 1.4 Figure 2.1 Figure 2.2 Figure 2.3 LIST OF FIGURES Approximation of J(G,R) = 0 ......................................................................... 13 Costly Reversible Investment without Fixed Costs ....................................... 14 Optimal Rule for Investment in Costly Reversible Investment without Fixed Costs Model ....................... 17 Optimal Rule for Disinvestment in Costly Reversible Investment without Fixed Costs Model ....................... 17 q(y) and N02) for Costly Reversible Investment with Fixed Costs ................. 21 Optimal Rule for Investment in Costly Reversible Investment with Fixed Costs Model ............................. 22 Optimal Rule for Disinvestment in Costly Reversible Investment with Fixed Costs Model ............................. 23 Figure 3.1 Schematic Diagram for Costly Reversible Investment with Fixed Costs ...... 25 Figure 3.2 Critical Values for Investment and Disinvestment ......................................... 29 Figure 4.1 Normalized Investment Function ................................................................... 44 Figure A] (102), N02), P'(y), and C' (y) for Two Period Model ....................................... 82 Figure A.2 Optimal Rule for Investment in Two Period Model ...................................... 84 Figure A.3 Optimal Rule for Disinvestment in Two Period Model ................................ 84 ix Figure 8.1 Figure 8.2 Figure B] Figure 8.1 Approximation of 6* (I) ............................................................................... 87 Figure B.2 Approximation of G* (2) ............................................................................... 88 Figure D.1 GFM vs OLS .......................................................... ’ ....................................... 95 ilhen a rim. stock- The“ condIIIOIIS “I take mm 390 decision. Th future inVCSIr analysis. This a into account II merging TONY order to incorp model with cos 11997,) use a mi model with hotI form Solution of nUmericaIIy. Th takes into accour Tobin's ('1 f . 0. capital exceed: Llie’mrginal belie hen eh! ofcapitaI i: D _ "DIIofnet cash; 1m , . isImem 13 an int INTRODUCTION When a firm invests, its investment decision is based upon its current level of capital stock. Then, firm’s current investment affects its future investment decisions by setting conditions upon which the firm makes its future decisions. Therefore, the firm should take into account the possibilities of future investment when it makes its investment decision. This paper shows the optimal investment decision for a firm contemplating future investment, and investigates actual investment in accordance with theoretical analysis. This analysis applies option pricing theory to capital investment in order to take into account the possibilities of future investment. Currently, Abel and Eberly are merging Tobin’s q theory with an adjustment cost function and irreversible investment in order to incorporate the possibility of future investment. Abel and Eberly (1996) use a model with costly reversibility but without fixed costs of investment. Abel and Eberly (1997) use a model with fixed costs of investment and irreversibility. This paper uses a model with both fixed costs of investment and costly reversibility. In general, a closed form solution of this model is unattainable. Therefore, this analysis solves the problem numerically. The theoretical analysis shows that Tobin’s q becomes lower, when a firm takes into account its future investment. Tobin’s (marginal) q theory implies that a firm invests when the marginal benefit of capital exceeds the marginal cost of capital. The firm will invest up to the point where the marginal benefit of investment becomes equal to the marginal cost. The marginal benefit of capital is Tobin’s q, and equal to the derivative of the present discounted value (PDV) of net cash flow or firm’s equity. The marginal cost is the price of capital. Investment is an increasing function of Tobin’s q. ThiS an 313515 com ICIBI’SIbIe in) int‘estmcm 0] model (GFNI lhe anaII'SIS ‘ irreversible in costs for HUN 1. Irrflmib If the tin“ can im‘ests heat”) and Tobin's (I ‘ ofcapital “ill I firm will want ‘- On the other ha information abc talue for the fir. accurate adjustn literature applies The irrex option is a right. e . . 0mm0d1ties at a future ' - The 1nt‘e‘: ET. \Cls exceeds the This analysis modifies the friction model to analyze actual investment. The analysis compares five different investment models including one that specifies costly reversible investment with fixed costs. The analysis shows that costly reversible investment or the corresponding econometric model, a generalized version of the friction model (GFM), is the best model to analyze actual investment among the tested models. The analysis also shows that an investment model of partial specification such as irreversible investment can be inferior to a model of reversible investment without fixed costs for empirical research. 1. Irreversibility, Costly Reversibility and Fixed Costs of Investment If the firm cannot sell its installed capital, investment is irreversible. When the firm invests heavily now, it is more likely that the firm will have too much capital in the future and Tobin’s q will be lower than the price of capital. In other words, the marginal benefit of capital will be less than the marginal cost of capital in the future. In such a case, the firm will want to sell its installed capital, but cannot due to the irreversibility of capital. On the other hand, if the firm postpones its investment decision, it will acquire more information about the economy and, then, can adjust its capital stock. Thus, waiting has value for the firm in a stochastic economy, and the firm’s gain from waiting is more accurate adjustment of its capital stock in the future. The irreversible investment literature applies option pricing theory in order to evaluate the value of waiting. The irreversibility literature regards future investment as a call option. A call option is a right, but not an obligation, for investors to buy financial assets or commodities at a predetermined price, or striking price, at a predetermined date in the future. The investors or option buyers exercise their option if the market price of the assets exceeds the striking price at the contract date. If the market price is lower than the striking price, the option buyers will not exercise their option. The gain for the option buyer is difference between the striking price and the market price at the maturity date. Therefore, the gain is kinked at the striking price. The gain is zero if the market price is ”A lower than 1h: is PtisitiW ant buyers ha“ I" option pricing In the S modeled as fur economiC indit 1111 estment of! The firm in\‘€51 Otherwise. the than the margin When tI‘ purchase price ( introduces anoti disint'estrnent b1 IInn the critical becomes equal t1 do w the resale resale price of ca intestment. the 1: positive when the economic indican aPUI Option lower than the striking price. If the market price is higher than the striking price, the gain is positive and increasing along with the market price. The premium that the option buyers have to pay to option writers is equal to the expected gain for the option buyer. Option pricing theory evaluates this premium. In the stochastic economy in this paper, operating profit and cash flows are modeled as functions of capital stock and a stochastic variable, which is called the economic indicator variable. For a given level of capital stock, there is a critical value for investment of the economic indicator variable, which corresponds to the striking price. The firm invests when the economic indicator is higher than the critical value. Otherwise, the firm does not invest, because the marginal benefit of investment is less than the marginal cost of investment. When the firm can sell its installed capital at a resale price lower than the purchase price of new capital, investment is costly reversible. Costly reversibility introduces another critical value of the economic indicator variable, the value at which disinvestment becomes profitable. The firm disinvests if the economic indicator is lower than the critical value for disinvestment. Then the firm will disinvest until Tobin’s q becomes equal to the resale price of capital. The firm does not disinvest if Tobin’s q is above the resale price. When Tobin’s q is between the purchase price of capital and the resale price of capital, zero investment, or inaction, is optimal. Similar to the gain from investment, the gain from disinvestment is kinked at the critical value. The gain is positive when the economic indicator is below the critical value and zero when the economic indicator is above the critical value; In the analysis, disinvestment is similar to a put option. When there are fixed costs for investment, fixed costs introduce a minimum amount of optimal investment. Sunk costs or installation costs of investment are examples of fixed costs of investment. Because of fixed costs, a value of Tobin’s q higher than the price of capital is not sufficient for optimality. An increase in the PDV of net Cash lIO“ the gain from investment ht disinvestment economic indi 2. Prior Wor Abel and Eber agents which i1 irreversibility. into their mode im'estment cost investment as \s' shows that a ran; and the costly re case. a constant r COmpetitit'e mark hfihatior. i.e.. the the Operating prof “hen the 1 lirm’s ”lathe! Com option pricing theo ,. titerature shows th" net cash flow from investment can be smaller than fixed costs. When the firm invests, the gain from investment should be larger than fixed costs. As a result, optimal investment has a minimum. If there are fixed costs for disinvestment, optimal disinvestment also has a minimum. Fixed costs also introduce a range of inaction in the economic indicator. 2. Prior Work Abel and Eberly have published several papers about capital investment by risk neutral agents which incorporate Tobin’s q theory with an adjustment cost function and irreversibility. Abel and Eberly (1994) formally incorporate fixed costs of investment into their model. They solve a continuous time model with a general form of the investment cost function which includes both fixed costs and the costly reversibility of investment as well as a conventional convex adjustment cost function. Their analysis shows that a range of inaction appears in the firm’s investment decision. Both fixed costs and the costly reversibility result in inaction as an optimal investment decision. In one case, a constant returns to scale (CRTS) Cobb-Douglas technology and a perfectly competitive market are assumed. This model results in the firm showing risk-loving-like behavior, i.e., the firm will invest more when the price of output fluctuates more, because the operating profit function is convex in the output price under those assumptions. When the firm contemplates an investment project, the firm can wait until the firm’s market condition becomes more favorable. McDonald and Siegel (1986) employ option pricing theory to evaluate the value of waiting. The irreversible investment literature shows that optimal investment has two states; one is strictly positive investment and the other is zero investment, and one of the two states appears at a time. Bemanke (1983) by employing option pricing theory shows an asymmetric character to irreversible investment. When market conditions for the firm are favorable, the firm will invest and acquire more capital. Because the firm cannot resell its installed capital, the firm should be worried about “bad news.” Due to the irreversibility of investment, the firm cannot is mg.- sell its installt can adjuSl its ‘ decision is C01 sensitin? IO 15 C urren and the irret‘er: articles cm er. incorporates ho model with the model is that “I ot’its capital stot ini'estment is [lit disinvestment. pl 0f the call Optior the distribution 01 mean-presen'ing 5 treatment. Table 1 R. \ Papers. % 1 L .lDI-‘Pt1996j! ) .lEtl996j 1! \ 31311997) i ‘ tarot 1999)" VIE an“ DEP ~ . Jaip’cl’lll‘ely “an sell its installed capital, even if a lower capital stock is optimal. In other words, the firm can adjust its capital stock upward but not downward. Thus, the firm’s investment decision is concerned only with bad news, because what “irreversible investment is sensitive to is ‘downside’ uncertainty (Bemanke, pp. 93).” Currently, Abel and Eberly are merging the adjustment cost function literature and the irreversibility literature. Table 1 shows recent articles and the topics which the articles cover. Abel, Dixit, Eberly and Pindyck (1996) develop a model which incorporates both Tobin’s q theory and option pricing theory. The model is a two period model with the costly reversibility, but without fixed costs. One conclusion from that model is that when the firm makes a decision it should take into account the adjustment of its capital stock in the future (the second period). The appropriate q for current investment is the derivative of the PDV of cash flow assuming no future investment or disinvestment, plus the value of the put option for future disinvestment, minus the value of the call option for future investment. Their analysis also shows that an upward shift in the distribution of shocks to the firm’s revenue increases the incentive to invest, while a mean-preserving spread in the distribution of the shocks has an ambiguous effect on investment. Table 1 Recent Literature on Adjustment Cost Function and Irreversibility Adjustment Cost Function Irreversibility Model Papers‘ Costly Fixed Convex Irreversi- Option Two Continuous Reversibility Costs Function bility Pricing Period Time AE (1994) X X X X ADEP(1996) X X X AE (1996) X X X AE (1997) X X X X Asano(l 999) X X X X X * AE and ADEP stand for Abel and Eberly, and Abel, Dixit, Eberly and Pindyck, respectively. _ ..—— "”5 Abel " turnout fixed calculated fro rate) x (porch! funcll0n \yhiCI The analysis U approximation Abel :1“ costs. The moc tunable. i.e.. 8' Capital SlOCIi. “ the econom}' IS I unable become: ins—elastic demafi tinn's output and utilization. The anal ys the costly reyersih utilization. The mt namely fixed costs and etlects of econt I 11' - ' dues for 0pt1mal it time t1ons for the mo 0t - Douer functions ti stations LVN Abel and Eberly (1996) use an investment model with the costly reversibility, but without fixed costs. The paper shows that the range of inaction is wider than that calculated from the Jorgenson’s user cost of capital, i.e., (real interest rate + depreciation rate) x (purchase price or resale price of capital). Their model uses an operating profit function which has constant returns to scale in capital stock and a demand shock variable. The analysis uses a Taylor approximation for its solution, but there are large approximation errors in some cases. Abel and Eberly (1997) use a model incorporating both irreversibility and fixed costs. The model shows that there are a trigger value and a target value for a composite variable, i.e., a random variable representing the ratio of economic conditions to current capital stock. When the composite variable exceeds the trigger value, which means that the economy is booming, the firm increases its capital stock such that the composite variable becomes the target value. The model uses a Cobb-Douglas technology, and an iso-elastic demand function. There are stochastic shocks to technology, the demand for a firm’s output and the price of flow input. The model also includes the level of factor utilization. . The analysis presented here uses a modified Abel and Eberly (1997) model with the costly reversibility. The analysis includes fixed costs, but excludes the factor utilization. The model without fixed costs is a special case of the model with fixed costs; namely fixed costs are zero. The analysis will quantitatively show optimal investment and effects of economic parameters on optimal investment. In order to derive critical values for optimal investment, there are two obstacles: solving a quotient of power functions for the model without fixed costs and solving a simultaneous equation system 0f power functions for the model with fixed costs. This analysis resorts to numerical solutions. Since costly reversible investment has three ranges in the economic indicator variable, the analysis employs a generalized version of the friction model. Maddala < —-"'s. (1981mm 16- mode]. which Variable is VIII Hou'eVCT. the one for inyesU modification t1 ditl’erent part5 analysis. The one tired costs. irre itithout fixed Ct are non-nested. test ofmodel sel Young's test 011 The empi quipment indust iDdUStn'es. costly A tncuon model is t htghest and its est (1983, pp. 162) discusses this model. The friction model is an extension of the Tobit model, which has two ranges. Tobin (195 8) studies a model in which a dependent variable is varying in one of the two ranges while it remains constant in the other range. However, the economic model of this analysis has three ranges in the economic indicator: one for investment, zero investment and disinvestment. The economic model requires a modification to allow some explanatory variables to have different coefficients in different parts of the friction model. Thus, the analysis generalizes the friction model for analysis. The analysis presented here compares five investment models: reversible without fixed costs, irreversible without fixed costs, irreversible with fixed costs, costly reversible without fixed costs, and costly reversible with fixed costs. Since some examined models are non-nested, the LR test is not appropriate for comparison. Voung (1989) proposes a test of model selection, which is an extension of the LR test. The analysis employs Voung’s test of model selection. The empirical analysis investigates three industries: the computer and office equipment industry, the automobile industry, and the airline industry. For all three industries, costly reversible investment with fixed costs or the corresponding generalized friction model is the best among the five investment models, since its likelihood is highest and its estimated coefficients are compatible with the economic model. . . 2., v" ' T‘- (OSI This chatcr “ Here. Z: and ’1‘- respectit'el}'- ' robsoouelie shifts a firm'5 ' tyith drift ‘U; N u a ‘ I lllrm S EXDCC' (1 costs. If. \yhicl F: . .uncuons I, and FL‘IICllOIl. respec . i‘Ic‘ fore. d], is Ofccapital up to t stock ’ ' . ,.IS expr CHAPTER 1 COSTLY REVERSIBLE INVESTMENT WITHOUT FIXED COSTS This chapter analyzes costly reversible investment without fixed costs. The analysis assumes that the operating profit function, 7:, has the following functional form. 7r(K,,Z, ) = A,,Z,""K,” (1) Here, Z, and K, are the stochastic economic indicator variable and capital stock, respectively. The specification of equation (1) can be derived for a firm with a CRTS Cobb-Douglas technology facing an iso-elastic demand curve. The economic indicator shifts a firm’s operating profits and is assumed to follow a geometric Brownian motion with drift ,uz and volatility 0'2. dZ, =,uZZ,dt+0'ZZ,dzz (2) Here, dz 2 is a standard Wiener process. The firm invests or disinvests to maximize the firm’s expected equity or the PDV of firm’s expected net cash flow, V(K,,Z,). The investment and disinvestment incur total costs, IC,, which include payments for investment, and receipts from disinvestment. The functions I, and D, are a cumulative investment function and a cumulative disinvestment function, respectively. The function I, is the sum of all purchases of capital up to time t. Therefore, d1, is the amount of investment at time 1. Similarly, D, is the sum of all sales of capital up to time t. Both are non-decreasing step functions. And, because capital stock, K,_, is exponentially depreciating at an exogenous rate, 5. while the functions I, and D: remain the K :1. D V Here}: [7; 111‘ price ofcapital the firm makes reyealed. in orc assuming optin' l-l. Bellman I By splitting the the second peri 1' Spread. 7~ Nu. is [IKI'ZI ) : E,‘ = A». A‘ + e 7”” s ,4: Z, The "lain text 01 :Wrmhes a Ivy 0 1 0.110 C I“tuition bacon] tit and Silt ' 0d 0 '. el D, remain the same level until the next investment or disinvestment, in general, K, at I, — D,. We can write the value function, V(K,,Z,), as follows.l V(K,,Z,)z max E,l:J:e'”{A,,Z,'j,”K,’i.ds—IC,,,}] (3) {ditto J11)!” i subject to dK,,_,. = d],,_. — dD,,,. — 5 K,,,.dt, Km. 2 0 Vs 2 O, dZHs : [1221+de + 0.2 Zt+stZ a and ICHs = pKdIH-s _ pKdDHs Here, y, p; and p; are the discount rate, the purchase price of capital and the resale price of capital, respectively. Parameters y, p; and pg. are given. At a point in time, t, the firm makes its decision about K, after the stochastic economic indicator variable, 2,, is revealed, in order to maximize its expected equity or expected PDV of the net cash flow assuming optimal investment for the future. l-l. Bellman Equation By splitting the time period of equation (3) into two: the first period from zero to AI, and the second period from At to infinity, and assuming that At is sufficiently small and the spread. y— ,uz, is strictly positive, we have V(K, , Z, ) = E, [ f e‘” A, Z,’,‘fK,‘i_,ds] + max E, i: fie” {AnZIl+—.i') Kris-(1S - [Cm i] I‘ll!“ JII)!1‘.I‘I Z, >13 +3—7A’ max E’|:J:e-fl {Aan-FzHrKZAHrdT— pKdIHAHr + pKdDHAHr }] {‘III+AI*fv(ll)I-t-~+f} = My pe— O, the above equation becomes Ill/(Kr ’ZI ) = Athl-oKrg+(1/d’)Et[dV(K19 21)] (6) By Ito’s lemma, E,[dV( - )] can be expressed as follows: E, [dV(K, ,Z, )] = —5 K,VKdt + szzZ,dt +é-szafiZfdt. (7) Thus, the Bellman equation for V( - ) is 7V(K,,Z, ) = A,Z,""K,” — 5 Ky, + fizzy, + $032,2sz . (8) Because V( - ) is set up to be homogeneous of degree one in K and Z by choosing the exponents on Z, we can transform the partial differential equation (8) to an ordinary differential equation. The derivative of the expected equity, VK, is equal to Tobin’s q. By defining y a Z, / K,, ,u, a ,uz + 6, and a; 2 0'2, q(y) ( 5 VA) becomes the following second order ordinary differential equation 2 (7 + 5Iq(y) = A149 y” + #.qu'(y)+ %yzq"(y). (9) The solution of equation (9) is q(y) = Hy”) + BNy‘”‘ + B,.y“’". (10) The first term of equation (10) is the particular solution, and H = AKB / f (1 — 61). Then the characteristic function f associated with equation (9) is given by mos—92w -[#_y-32’—']¢+(7+5)- (11) The second term and the third term of equation (10) are the complementary solution. The second term corresponds to the derivative of the value of future disinvestment as the put 10 option and 11 the call optic I-Z. Optim: The optimal ot‘costly rey: purchase pric resale price 0 to the corresp When one for intest. lithe firm 1': Place. \yhile be Similar Propert and “16 first two cor Lhe high Order Co I“ . B.” and 8,, Abei and 1 hon . option and the third term corresponds to the derivative of value of future investment as the call option. And, the exponents (pp (< 0) and (0,. (> I) solve fl (p) = 0. 1-2. Optimal Investment for Costly Reversible Investment without Fixed Costs The optimal investment decision equates Tobin’s q with the price of capital. In the case of costly reversible investment, the firm should buy new capital when q exceeds the purchase price of capital, while it should sell its installed capital when q is lower than the resale price of capital. Then, the firm invests or disinvests until Tobin’s q becomes equal to the corresponding price of capital. When there are no fixed costs for investment, there are two critical values in y: one for investment and the other for disinvestment. At the critical value for investment, y+ , the firm is indifferent between investing and waiting. Above y" , investment takes place, while below y+ the firm waits. The critical value for disinvestment, y” has similar properties. Then, the boundary conditions for equation (10) are fourfold: q(y‘)=pZ-, (128) q(y‘)=p;-, ' (12b) q'(y*)=0. (12c) and q'(y‘)=0. (12d) The first two conditions are the smooth pasting conditions. The last two conditions are the high order contact. For investment without fixed costs, there are four unknowns, y+ , y~ , BN, and B”. Abel and Eberly (1996) derive the solution to equation (10) which satisfies the boundary conditions (12a) to (12d) as Bi, = —(‘—'¢‘-’)—Hg(6)(y‘ )""“"‘ , (13a) N 3,. =—-(‘—‘—9)—’i[1—g(0)1(y')""“”". (13b) I) ll and Here. U 5 .1. dosh—U- equation ohere. R E 17,-: Abel an point (I? = 1 am But. usually R > approximation. t1 For example. “he actually 5.43. An West term in ei t he function 17. T Flt aP'Proximation as fi appendix B , . p2 ":5 __ , 13 y iA,ahG"i ' ( C) and y‘ = [TAT—pL—jT—o. ' (13d) Here, G a y’ /y-, g(x)E (x"’" —x'—")/(x“’r -—x"’" ) and h(x) a [1 — (1 — t9)g(x)/(0N — (1 - 6){1 — g(x)}_/¢,, 1/_/'(1 — 0). Here, G satisfies the following equation J(R,G) a Rh(G)— G"”h(G" )= 0 (14) where, R a p; /p,; . Abel and Eberly (1996) solve equation (14) by a Taylor approximation at the point (R = l and G = 1). They suggest 60'2 G=1+i(t—9)(;+6 But, usually R > 1 and G > I. When the solution is far from the point of the Taylor )]M (R -1)'”‘ . (15) approximation, there is a large approximation error. Figure 1.] shows such an example. For example, when R = 2, Abel and Eberly suggest that G is approximately 1.51, but G is actually 5.43. An alternative approximation for equation (14) can be derived by choosing a larger term in either the numerator or the denominator in the function g for simplifying the function h. The alternative approximation yields equation (16), which is a better approximation as figure 1.] shows.2 G {[MIKP—jm—mijw (16) (01' ‘1+6 CON 2 See the appendix B for derivation. Equation (16) 5 equation ('14) n Figure 1 costs. Since 0 «- function. H1 ,Dositiyey. And. iiunction. 8.j~' intinite at}: z 0 l B. < 0. the third t The third term eq infinity. So that it i», ’here are a I Um I it the q funCllon at tsdtattn as a fume“ 0-351 '1 . _ 10' Figure 1.1 Approximation of J(R,G) = 0 (Oz 0.143, A,z 0.506, 5: 0.06, y: 0.07, #2 = 0.05, 0'; = ,uz) Equation (16) suggests that G is approximately 6.07. However, this analysis solves equation (14) numerically in order to find more accurate results. Figure 1.2 shows one solution for costly reversible investment without fixed costs. Since 0 < t9< 1, H> 0 and O < 1 — t9< 1. Therefore, the first term of the q function, Hy” , which is equal to the so-called naive case, is concave and increasing for positive y. And, the term is zero at y = 0. Since (0N < 0 and Bo > 0, the second term of the q function, 8,, y"’"' , is convex and decreasing for positive y. As the second term is infinite at y = 0, it dominates the other terms for small positive y. Since (pp > 1 and B, < 0, the third term of the q function, B,.y"’" , is concave and decreasing for positive y. The third term equals zero at y = 0, and approaches negative infinity as y approaches infinity, so that it dominates the other terms for large positive y. As a result, for positive y, there are a local minimum of the q function at a small value in y and a local maximum of the q function at a large value in y. Figure 1.2 (a) shows the (marginal) q ratio, which is drawn as a function of y. The q function is negatively sloped for y < y“ , then positively sloped, peaks at y” , and again becomes negatively sloped. The q function is FIQUIL l9s0l43 (a) Functions q (y) and My) q t y ) p x 1——-— . \-— l I l I 0 5—-/— I / | I I 1 ’ ( D ) y 1' t I > 0 2 Y (b) Optimal Investment and Disinvestment d I t / ( I ) t 0 > y 0 [/r Z t /K t Figure 1.2 Costly Reversible Investment without Fixed Costs (19:: 0.143, A,z 0.506, 5: 0.06, y: 0.07,;1, = 0.05, a, = 112. G e 5.43) tangential [0 function is 11‘ is presented 1 ,\' function i5 For Ci abQVC .1" 01' inyests or dis: Value. y" 01' . optimal. and c installation of For the naiye c left of the costl than those for t Figure 1 function of the 1 In figure 1.2 t b) reyersible inyest lines are deriyed myestment is opt Optimal inyestme Ifthe ratio is beloy tangential to the price lines ( p; = 1 and p; = 0.5 ) at the critical values of y. The N function is the so-called naive case in which the firm assumes zero future investment. It is presented as a dashed line in figure 1.2 (a). The bold line of either the q function or the N function is relevant to investment decisions. For costly reversible investment without fixed costs, whenever the firm observes y above y+ or below y' , the firm will invest or disinvest accordingly. When the firm invests or disinvests, y after investment or disinvestment equals the corresponding critical value, y“ or y" . When y is between y” and y‘ , zero investment, or inaction, is optimal, and capital stock remains at the same level. Since this model assumes that installation of investment is instantaneous, we do not observe y above y or below y‘ . For the naive case, the optimal investment rule (the bold dashed line) is entirely located left of the costly reversible case (the bold solid line), and two critical values are lower than those for the costly reversible case. Figure 1.2 (b) shows optimal investment, dl,, and optimal disinvestment, dD,, as a function of the ratio of the stochastic variable, Z, to capital stock before investment, K _. In figure 1.2 (b), a solid line is optimal investment and disinvestment for the costly reversible investment, and a dashed line is optimal investment for the naive case. Both lines are derived from figure 1.2 (a). When the ratio, Z, / K,_. is between y+ and y’ , zero investment is optimal so that K,, = K,_, or d], = O and d0, = 0. If the ratio exceeds y+ , optimal investment is positive and given by .11, =—ZL—K,_. (17) If the ratio is below y" , optimal disinvestment is positive and given by d0, = K,_ — 2:. (18) y Investmfm 1" that. when ‘h‘ “hell ll doc‘S 2 located left of the firm come stock. the tint it does not. F1 gure. respectiyely. ' 11 heneyerj' mt inyestment is 0 1p; 1 from belt intestrn'ent. y" Opposite moye. the resale price I Investment for the naive case is entirely located left of costly reversible investment, so that, when the firm contemplates future investment, its optimal investment is smaller than when it does not consider future investment. Disinvestment for the naive case is also located left of costly reversible investment, so that optimal disinvestment is larger when the firm contemplates future disinvestment than when it does not. In terms of capital stock, the firm chooses lower capital stock when it consider future investment than when it does not. Figures 1.3 and 1.4 show the optimal rule for investment and disinvestment, respectively. The optimal rule is to bring y back to one of the two critical values whenever y moves beyond the corresponding critical value. Otherwise, inaction or zero investment is optimal. In figure 1.3, the function q approaches the purchase price line ( p}; ) from below, becomes tangent to the purchase price line at the critical point for investment, y+ , and then moves downward. In figure 1.4, the function q shows the opposite move. It approaches the resale price line ( p;- ) from above, becomes tangent to the resale price line at the critical point for disinvestment, y‘ , and then moves upward. Figure 1.3 Optimal Rule for Investment in Costly Reversible Investment without Fixed Costs Model (Hz 0.143, A,z 0.506, a: 0.06, 7: 0.07, #2 = 0.05. 02 = #2. y e 2.01) CJ(Y) / / / / 0.81L / ‘ / / / / <1(3’) 0.6 / / / / - N(Y)/ y p” 0.4 / z - 0 0.3 06 Y Figure 1.4 Optimal Rule for Disinvestment in Costly Reversible Investment without Fixed Costs Model (61:: 0.143, A,z 0.506, a: 0.06, y: 0.07,;1z = 0.05. a, = #2. y' e 0.369) COS This chapter der fixed costs. both y. The inyestme on one hand. and marginal analysis reyersible inyestn We can 111 from intestment v subj Here’ F/ZIei and I Coefficients. F1 an folloyying Bellman 1 " CHAPTER 2 COSTLY REVERSIBLE INVESTMENT WITHFIXED COSTS This chapter derives the optimal investment rule when investment has fixed costs. Due to fixed costs, both investment and disinvestment have a trigger value and a target value in y. The investment costs have two parts: payment for new capital or revenue from resale on one hand, and fixed costs on the other hand. Fixed costs, however, do not affect the marginal analysis of investment, so that the Bellman equation is the same as costly reversible investment without fixed costs. We can write the value function, V(K,,Z,), as follows. There is one difference from investment without fixed costs. i.e., a specification of fixed costs. V(K,,Z,)= max E,[Ee‘”{A,,Z,'jf’K,”,,ds—1C,,,.}:l (19) :(IIH. .dl),,,} subject to dK,,_,. = all,” — dD,,,. — 5 K,,,dt, K,,, 2 0 Vs 2 0, dZHs = #2 Zl+.i‘dt + 02 ZI+.\'dZZ 9 and [CH-.1- : [71261],” " pKdDHs + FIZt+x + FDZHx Here, F, Z,” and F ,,Z,,_,. are fixed costs for investment and disinvestment, respectively. Coefficients, F, and F D are constant and given. Then, equation (19) yields the following Bellman equation. 1-0 0 1 2 2 yV(K,,Z,)= AnZ, K, -5 Ky, + pzzyz + 56,2, V2, (20) The solution of equation (20) is Vx(- )= q(y) = Hy” + Biyi‘ + Biy‘” - (21) Here, H, (pi: and (p,. are defined similar to investment without fixed costs. 2.]. Optimal omamsflwtr .- ,9 .and .‘ .lrr' . "' and At the trigger ya} int'esting. Equal until function q l" lllbl. The benel fixed costs of 1m disinyestment y 1e Although hincnon q \yithou p. satisfy ti. q “Ithout fixed c0 hononmga, lowers. Similarly , .1 St came appendix 1 2-1. Optimal Investment for Costly Reversible Investment with Fixed Costs Denoting the trigger values and the target values of investment and disinvestment by y}, , y}, , y}; , and y,’.u , respectively, the boundary conditions for equation (21) become qui. )= pi . ’ (22a) qui..l= pi, (22b) qui. )= p; . (22c) qu-I..l= pi. (22d) Bil” (' l- Pi I“ = ”I , (22c) and fill); - VK (- )]dK = ZF,, . (221) At the trigger value for investment, the firm is indifferent between investing and not investing. Equation (22a) represents this. When the firm invests, the firm should invest until function q becomes equal to the purchase price of capital. This yields equation (22b). The benefit from investment from the trigger value to the target value is equal to fixed costs of investment. Equation (22c) shows this. Similar arguments for disinvestment yield equations (22c), (22d), and (221). Although the function q with fixed costs has the same equation form as the function q without fixed costs, two coefficients for the function q with fixed costs, BL and BI. , satisfy the following relation with the corresponding coefficients for the function q without fixed costs, BN and 3,).3 By < B; < 0 < Bi, < BN (23) By multiplying a positive coefficient smaller than BN, the minimum of the function q lowers. Similarly, by multiplying a negative coefficient larger than B,., the maximum of 3 See the appendix C for proof. the function 4 Values for 1hs‘ conditit‘nS (*2: From ' r. l-. and r... til = - flc e r ‘ 315 a \‘CClt ::’Ll'. ‘ v r I \ ‘,.'lv"ru. I" C l" ’ . equations (24 Figure 2.1 Fe ' he solid line is 11 Til . thout fixed cost the function q rises. By choosing appropriate B}, and B}. , the model yields positive values for the four critical values, y}, . YT, , y-f-u . and y], , satisfying the boundary conditions (22a) to (220. From equations (21) and (22a) to (22f), we have F. (e) = H01. 1‘" + at (yr-.1" + B: (511,)“ — p: = 0. (24a) )= )H(yi. )' "+B;(y1..) + 8; (yr-.1” — pi = 0. (24b) (5):éc:=1‘1(y,,l9+8i,.,‘(y.,)w’wL BM)“ —p;,=0, (24c) =H(y1‘.1 )1 0 +8 811011,)“ 813(3)], I” - p2 = 0, (24d) A, 1p. —1 + 1p. -1 F5(5)=::1__—6)[(y1r)0—(yn1)-0+](p8 -(y1-..l l B' (24c) + (011 '_1 [(3% l”—I -(y1§.)""’_'l+(p/01EN[boy/id)"I —(y1*~.)“' l— F1 = 0. and 131(6) = -p12l(y11.ll -(y13)_' l+ 7&7) [(321 I” -(y1‘-,)”l (24f) — (of: 1lfy-1'~..)“"" —(y11)"’"" - ,1? ”_ 1l(yi.)"”"' — (yr. )‘”"" l— E. = 0. Here, 6} is a vector of six unknowns for investment with fixed costs, where 6 = {y-,’-,, y},,, y}, , y;,,, B; , B}. }. This analysis again numerically solves the system of equations (24a) to (241). Figure 2.1 shows one solution of costly reversible investment with fixed costs. The solid line is the function q for investment with fixed costs, while a broken line is q without fixed costs. And, a dashed line is the function N. The difference between q with fixed costs and without fixed costs is only the inclusion of fixed costs, while all other conditions are the same. When there are fixed costs, the peak of the function q moves upward and to the right. As a result, the function q reaches above the purchase price line 20 1p; :1), An. mmgponds ltl same time. the minimum of th. betoeen the fur. or the left hand ofthe function (1 disinyest. while in either part (0 1 diff <"‘1‘:J < If” < FiQUre 2 ( p; = l ). And, the crescent area between the function q and the purchase price line corresponds to fixed costs of investment, or the left hand side of equation (22c). At the same time, the minimum of the function q moves downward and to the left, and the minimum of the function q is below the resale price line ( p; =9 0.5 ). A triangular area between the function q and the resale price corresponds to fixed costs of disinvestment, or the lefi hand side of equation (22f). The peak of the function q is flat, while the trough of the function q is steep. When y reaches part (D) in figure 2.1, the firm should disinvest, while when y reaches part (I) in the figure, the firm should invest. If y remains in either part (O), (O'), or (0"), then zero investment is optimal. Also, figure 2.1 shows ~ — + + yo :.- 53% 93.3) ~30..~.-.-.U Auwv highwwwbomwuw 2.210212%) «laserswvxmrev‘ 323.3% (a) Critical value for investment, y” _ (b) Target value for investment, y}, (c) Trigger value for investment, y; Costl Reversible with Fixed Costs 29 Figure 3.2 Critical Values for Investment and Disinvestment 0.5, F, = 0.5, FD = 0.5) 0.05, p;=1, pg= (19:: 0.143, A,z 0.506, 5=0.06, 0'2 .’---.‘.— 3.. J:9..C~a3>:._z:v AOL. 03:3; .35.:me A?» w. 30.0 EU Kiwi. .35 Ga .. so» 99%.. Emu)“ vw \5 c 713.0 ((1) Critical value for disinvestment, y‘ ;— ible without Fixed Costs Costl Revers j ersible with Fixed Costs Costly Rev (t) Trigger value for disinvestment, y;, (e) Target value for disinvestment, yr}, 30 Figure 3 .2 (cont’d) 35 figure 3: the linear aI approximati flgures in par to unity. so th' By test equal to zero. 1 hl‘l‘OIhesis u. it} ll . ere, flout: ar. 11 . ellOmlnalOr is ‘allables. Tap: [elem The h\p( , 3' . as figure 3.2 ((1) shows. As a result, the semi-log linear approximation is a better fit than the linear approximation. With the parameters for figure 3.2, the linear or semi-log linear approximations of all six critical values and their R2 are as follows: y+ =0.775+18.4> 2*(= y;,K,_), (38-a) by (O) K,,th, ifZ'SZ,_<_Z+, (38-b) and (D) K,, = Z,/y;.,, if z, < Z‘(= y;,1<,__). (38-c) Both axes in figure 3.1 are normalized by pre-investment capital stock, K,_, so that firm’s size does not affect the analysis. After both axes are natural-logged, the schematic diagram becomes figure 4.1. In figure 4.1, investment locus and disinvestment locus are parallel, and their slope is forty five degree. I I LnG' —————— | : I I I I I I 1 (01 1 (I) Lnyfrr Lnyfrr Ln (Zn/Kc-l Figure 4.1 - Normalized Investment Function 44 This K»). {Cli’resc represented for 311315.515. By USlng [hC and G : l1" (O) k-:0 (D) k: = L The theoretical are functions 01 variable. Th C)’ 1 L L1 L11 Here. :, is a vecto constant). This a1 otehastic variablt Intestment and t 11‘ M00168 ( ’7( = 3p; This analysis uses annual data. The capital stock at the beginning of the period, KM, represents post-investment capital stock, K,+. Pre-investment capital stock, K,-, is represented by 12'" K,. By assuming a depreciation rate ( 5 )_, the measure of investment for analysis, k,, is k, = Ln(KH /K,_ ) = Ln(Km /K, )+ a . (39) By using the ratios of the critical values as G + = y}; /y,+.u ( > 1 ), G" = y}, /y,70 (< l ), and G = y; /y.,‘., (> 1 ), the optimal investment rule becomes as follows: (I) k, = -Ln y}, + Ln(Z, /K, )+ 5 = LnG+ — Ln y}, + Ln(Z, /K, )+ 5, if Ln(Z, /K, )+ 5 > Ln y], (40-a) (0) k, = 0, if Ln y;,(= Ln y; — LnG): Ln(Z, /K, )+ a s Ln y; (40-b) (D) k, = LnG‘ — Ln y;, + LnG + Ln(Z, /K, )+ a, if Ln(Z, /K, )+ 5 < Ln y; — LnG (40-C) The theoretical model shows that the logarithms of the four values, y; , G+ , G" , and G are functions of economic parameters such as the spread and trend of the stochastic variable. They can be approximated by linear equations. Ln y}; =fi( spread, pg, 6, A,, 0'2, fixed costs, pg. ) z z,v (41-a) LnG” =f2( spread, ,uz, 6, A,, 02, fixed costs, pf, ) z z,v; (41-b) Ln G ' =f3( spread, pg, 6, A,, 0“,, fixed costs, pg. ) z z,v; (4l-c) LnG =fi( spread, pg, 6, A,, 0'2, fixed costs, pg. ) z z,vg (4l-d) Here, 2, is a vector of parameters, where z, E (spread, pg, 02, 6, A,, fixed costs, pg , constant). This analysis assumes that the depreciation rate (6), trend and volatility of the stochastic variable ([12 and 02), the operating profit function (A,r Z,"0K,9 ), fixed costs of investment, and the resale price of capital ( p; ) are all constant over time. Therefore, 2, becomes ( y( = spread + #2 ), constant). 45 Ther and technolo tinn's output technology is coefficients. assuming frict Re. is the firm 01 l - 1’5) 31 degree one in 1 In addit and Variance 0 Also. the econo possible heteror yr. 5 Ln( Zr :1 Ln([1 :1 Ln(k ISL“); There are two additional assumptions about the market demand of a firm’s output and technology to measure the economic indicator variable, Z,. The market demand of firm’s output is assumed to be iso-elastic, i.e., Q, = (1)/Xl )5 ( 8> 1 ), and, the technology is Cobb-Douglas, i.e., Q = X 2K “L” . Both X . and X, are stochastic coefficients. Then, the stochastic variable, Z,, is the product of X l and X2, and, by . . . . . -a _ . (l—at— I, assummg frlctlonless adjustment of flow mputs, Z, = [Re,K, (wL),/i" T/ l ). Here, Re, is the firm’s revenue ( = PQ ), (wL), is the cost of flow inputs, and a, and )6, are a( 1 — 1/6‘) and ,6 (1 — 1/5) , respectively. The stochastic variable, Z,, is homogeneous of degree one in Re,, K,, and (wL), under these assumptions. In addition, there is an error, u,, which is assumed to be normal with zero mean and variance 0'2 , and independent and identically distributed, i.e., u, ~ i.i.d. N[0, 0'2 ]. Also, the econometric model includes company dummy variables which represent possible heterogeneity among firms. By defining y, 5 Ln( Z, /K, ) + dummy variables + u, =(Ln(Re.),Ln(K1), Ln((wL).))( 1 / VI, -( 1 - ,3: )/ W, - fl./ VI)’ + dummies +u, = ( Ln(Re,), Ln(K,), Ln((wL),), d1, d2, d3, ) 77 + u, = x, 7] + u,, fl 5 Ln y; - 6w 2“,, V,, 21.1.6.5 ( 7), and vfs (coefficient for y), the econometric model becomes the following. ( 1 ) k. = 21V; + 16.77 - anvf + 14,, if x,77 + u, > z,,,,,.v_, (42-a) (O) k,=0, ifz v —z,vg5x,77+u,Sz v ' (42-b) l,nm.' [ IJmc f (D) k, = z,v; +x,77—z,.,,,,.v, +z,v, +u,, if x,77+u, 1,2,- when two models are nested, and q ’ , I) n""2 LR( - )/ a} —>N[ 0, 1 ], when two models are non-nested. A ! Here, LR(6 )7): ZLnlf(Y,'X,;6)/g(Y,|X,;}9)J and (2)2 = (Mn): {Ln[f(1’,lX,;6)/g(1’,|X,;)7)]}2 —{(1/n)ZLn[f(Y, the classical LR test is a special case in Voung’s test of model selection.4 X,;6)/g(Y,|X,;;7)]}2. Thus, (c) Test of Serial Correlation This analysis examines whether residuals, 2?, , are serially correlated. The test is based upon Wooldridge (1995, pp351). The null hypothesis is that there is no serial correlation. This test uses three types of residuals. Two are residuals from OLS and residuals from the GF M. Another is residuals from a two step estimation (TSE) for a limited dependent variable model.5 The reason that this analysis includes TSE residuals is that the test of serial correlation in this analysis is based upon OLS residuals and the second step of the TSE is OLS. The procedure is two steps. lst step: regress the lagged OLS residuals or the lagged GFM residuals, 1? on 1.1-1 9 x, and z,,, or regress the lagged TSE residuals on x,,, z, and the estimated inverse Mills ratio. Then, save the residuals, f. I,I—l ‘ ‘ Appendix D discusses the test of model selection under the serially correlated error assumption. 5 Appendix E shows the TSE and its results. 50 2nd step: ( under homoskedasticity assumption ) regress 12,, on r, The t- .I—I ' statistics on 0.1—1 is asymptotically normal under the null hypothesis. ( under heteroskedasticity assumption) regress 1 on 17,, xr', Then, .I—l ' N i 2(7). — 1) — SSR is asymptotically chi-squared of degree one under the null i=1 hypothesis. (d) Determination of Depreciation Rate, 6 In order to estimate the depreciation rate, 6, the analysis repeats the procedure with different values of the assumed depreciation rate and its range. The estimate of the depreciation rate is determined by four criteria: ( 1 ) high likelihood, ( 2 ) homogeneity of degree one for Z,, ( 3 ) the signs of the estimated critical ratios, i.e., Ln G+ >0, LnG‘ <0, and Ln G >0, and ( 4 ) superiority of the GFM. (e) Testing Hypotheses a. ( Ho ) 77R,.+ 7711+ 77..., = 0; this is a test of whether the ratio, Z, / K,, is homogeneous of degree zero in the firm’s revenue, capital stock and costs of flow inputs. ( Wald test ) This substitutes for a test of whether Z, is homogeneous of degree one in the three variables. b. ( Ho ) two competing investment models are equivalent vs ( Ha ) one model is better than the other. ( Voung’s Test of Model Selection ) 51 CHAPTER 5 INDUSTRY ANALYSIS This chapter examines three industries: the computer and the office equipment industry (SIC 3570), the automobile industry (SIC 3711), and the airline industry (SIC 4511), in accordance with the procedure in chapter 4. The analysis chooses three or four firms from each industry. The analysis confirms that actual investment is compatible with the theoretical analysis. 5-1. Computer and Office Equipment Industry i. Estimation and Measure of Zero Investment Table 5.1 shows the measure of zero investment for the computer and office equipment industry. According to the four criteria, the case with net capital stock, 6 = —0.005, A6 = 0.01,, and n = l is most compatible with the economic model, although cases with 6 close to zero show very similar results.6 Then, the measurement of investment for this analysis is Ln( K,,. / K, ) - 0.005. The case has a high likelihood, the sum of the estimated coefficients for the three financial variables is not significantly different from zero, the signs of the critical ratios are appropriate, and the OF M has the highest 6 There are two issues with a negative depreciation rate, 6. One is that the depreciation rate used for net capital stock is the accounting rate, rather than the physical or economic depreciation rate. In the cases with net capital stock, 6 represents the difference between the accounting depreciation rate and the economic equivalent. The accounting depreciation rate could be larger than the economic rate. Another issue is that of the price of capital. The book value of capital depends upon the acquiring costs of capital, or the purchase price of capital. Even if a firm buys the same capital goods, their prices vary from time to time. In general, old capital goods are cheaper than new ones due to the inflation. Consequently, the book value of capital stock could underestimate older capital, so that the estimated depreciation rate can be negative. 52 .688 2:888 05 ~33 0338800 ”20m The» $3 =8§m-§oz 33820 05 E “50$:me 2a Eon—802: .«o 380 Bfibemunfii 8 1 1:851: 51:5 8.7m? 8515.3. . _m N e 8 3.91:...— 36123 8515.: 351:...— 86123 _ So 86 az 321$ 381$ 881$ 331$ 881$ 851$; 22.18%.” a. N a 8 851:...— 8...1E£ $515.... 35155 851:?— _ So 3o 82 831$ 881$ 381$ 881$ 381$ 8515... 8515: a. a 2 8 2.51:...— 8...1:E omen—:5 2.51:?— RfE: _ 8.0 Bed 62 321$ 881$ 881$ 881$ 881$ 8.615: 8.615..— a. a 2 8 931:...— E...1:E 8515...— evanai 861:5 _ So 23 62 821$ 281$ 881$ 291$ 881$ caéflfi—sm ABATE—.5 A080 ace 2. N : 8 8.51:...— RTEE £513...— STE: 351:?— _ So wood: 82 521$ 881$ 881$ 891$ 881$ 8.61.8..— 8515: 2. m : 8 «2.1:...— 2...1:_.& 8.01:3 2.91:...— 2...1:_.£ _ So So: 62 321$ 381$ 881$ 381$ 881$ 8.915..— 851:...— 3 e : 8 861:?— Sdurwa 861:? 861:? 86135 _ 8.0 8.? 62 381$ 31$ 881$ 331$ 881$ 8.83: 8.83: 8 m z 8 861:3 86135 8.0135 861:? 861:5 _ 5o 8.? 62 281$ 881$ 881$ 531$ 281$ . A: 2: 2: 38. 2.5 SE 86a 0 658 So 83 .2 m 3.80 San Mo 59834 ~08: mosoaocoom mo 0.5.6.32 3.3st “58“”ch 8E0 98 839208 “:25ng EoN mo 83on mm 035. 53 685—328 a 5685 3:98 mo 28.: 05 >6: 526% 5:28 55$ 9.: E A a v .5 A a V .. .3on 28288 05 53> 03:59:00 6.0m :53 24 583085532 33555—5 05 .3 5:85:85 85 552582: mo $85 voxEEnmntm 8 1 i. +65 1.5 51:5 851:5 555155 3 5 : 8 851:5 851:5 851:5 551:5 251:5 AeN 85 55 az NN551$ 881$ 551$ 881$ 321$ 55. _15N5 555155 2. 5 : a 851:5 851:5 851:5 851:5 851:5 AeN S5 555 62 881$ 881$ 281$ 5N.81$ 351$ 85155 85155 3 _ : 8 351:5 851:...— 5551:5 851:5 $5155 3N 85 85. az 881$ 381$ 881$ NN81$ 881$ 55.555 3. N 2 hm 05968 oodLZE 8.0.1255 8.0":th oodnftm Svm :3 mod- 82 9855 881$ 381$ 381$ 881$ 851%... 555155 2. N 5 8 851:5 851:5 851:5 251:5 851:5 EN _55 85 az 881$ 881$ 581$ 881$ 381$ 5551a?— 555155 2. _ S 8 851:5 851:5 851:5 851:5 851:5 EN 85 555 62 881$ 881$ 881$ 881$ 381$ 8515.... 555155 8 m : 8 351:5 851:5 851:5 251:5 351:5 EN 85 85- az 381$ 881$ £81$ 881$ 281$ 55835 3.15 8 v : 8 851:5 251:5 551:5 851:5 851:5 EN 85 N55- 62 - 881$ 281$ 881$ 281$ 881$ , :5 A 3 35 865 28 5 865 o 88. So we»; 3 5 8:56 , Sun— .«0 558:2 _ovcz mambo—concom .«o 9:68: 9.585 E. 2.5 54 5555505555855 55 :55 :wsofi 5505 .5585 much,» 55 5555 0355.553 250 5552 5. ® 50on 0555505508 255 53» 0355555555500 520m :58 $3 5505555055-:5Eoz 5.8555550 55 3 555.505.5285 5555 55558555255 .50 5558 55855 B55513: :5 1 .25 +8 +.§51:5 55515155 5551815 55 51 5. 55 @1555 851:5 @1555 851:5 8.51:5 5 85 55.5 58555 881$ 881$ 55.551$ 8.551$ 881$ 5551555 5551555 . N5 5 5 55 @1555 851:5 @1555 851:5 8.51:5 5 85 5.5.5 585 881$ 555.551$ 55.551$ 55.551$ 55.551$ 5551555 5551555 55 5 5 55 @1555 851:5 5551555 8.51:5 8.51:5 5 85 85 585 381$ 281$ 5.5.551$ 8.551$ 881$ 8.35 35 55 N 5 55 @1555 851:5 851:5 5551555 5551555 5 8.5 8.5 585 881$ 881$ 55.551$ 8.551$ 55.551$ 5551555 555155 5 55 N 5 55 851:5 8.51:5 «5.51:5 8.51:5 8.51:5 5 8.5 55.5 552 55.551$ 8.551$ 55.551$ 55.551$ 55.551$ 5551555 5551555 55 5 5 55 851:5 851:5 851:5 5551555 851:5 5 8.5 85 5oz 55.81$ 881$ 881$ 881$ 55.551$ 5551555 5551555 8 v 5 55 351:5 5.51:5 851:5 851:5 5.551555 5 8.5 8.5 552 55.551.$ 55.551$ 55.551.$ 55.81$ 55.551$ 5 5551555 55. 5 55 55 «551:5 5551555 851:5 5551555 5551555 5 8.5 851 5oz 8.551$ 55.55.1$ 55.551$ 55.5v1$ 881$ 555 505 :55 585.5 2.50 25555 5555.5. a 5555.5 5.50 5.8.5 555 5 55.5580 359 mo 509.532 _ovoz moEoEOQOOM mo own—mac: 555.5585 5.5 55555 55 likelihood in the five competing models. When the analysis uses gross capital stock, the sum of the estimated coefficientS, 77).... 77K and 77...), seems to be significantly different from ZCI‘O . Table 5.2 shows the estimated coefficients of the best case with net capital stock, 6 = —0.005, A6: 0.01 and n = l. The sum of the estimated coefficients, 77"., 77K and 77...), is —0.019, which is very close to zero. The log likelihood of the GFM exceeds the log likelihood of the next best model, which is OLS, by a margin of about nine. Fixed costs of disinvestment seem larger than fixed costs of investment, since the absolute value of the estimated constant for v; is about three times greater than the estimated constant for v; for the GFM. Those estimated constants are —O.616 and 0.225, respectively. Table 5.2 Estimation of Computer and Office Equipment Industry OLS Tobit G Tobit RFM GFM g... O.671(O.12) 0.642(0.13) 0.493(0.13) O.698(O.l3) 0.559(0.13) 27,. -0.386(0.05) -O.371(0.06) -O.327(0.06) -0.396(0.06) -O.351(0.06) m1. -0.309(0.07) -O.297(0.08) -O.190(0.08) -O.325(0.08) -0.227(0.07) d1 (DEC) -0.461(0.30) -o.405(0.30) -O.730(63.3) -o.499(0.31) -0.591(116) d2 (HWP) -O.478(0.30) -O.426(0.31) -0.774(63.3) -o.513(0.32) -0.635(116) d3 (IBM) -0.407(0.34) -O.358(0.34) -0.660(63.3) -0.446(0.35) -0.531(1 16) V,:y -0.019(0.01) -0.019(0.01) -0.010(15.4) -0.020(0.01) 0.040(31.6) V,: 7 N/A N/A N/A 0.001(0.01) 0.005(46.2) 12,: _cons N/A N/A N/A 0.015(0.02) 0.764(161) V; : y N/A N/A 0.006(15.4) N/A 0.057(31.6) 15;: _cons N/A N/A O.480(63.3) N/A 0.225(1 16) .4: y N/A N/A N/A N/A 0.026(33.8) .4: _cons N/A N/A N/A N/A -O.616(1 12) a 0.086(0.01) 0.078(0.01) 0.068(0.01) 0.088(0.01) 0.071(0.01) Pr[2n=0] 0.345 0.272 0.250 0.372 0.378 Ln L, 62.397 45.693 59.658 52.502 71.366 Standard errors in parentheses Parameters: net capital stock, 6: —0.005, A6: 0.01, and n = 1 Number of observations: total 60, investment 47, zero investment 2, and disinvestment ll ii. Test of Model Selection Table 5.3 shows the statistics that Voung (1989) proposed for model selection. Two cases: (a) Tobit vs G Tobit and (b) the RFM vs the GFM, are nested so that the classical LR test is valid. All other cases are non-nested. According Voung’s test of model selection, the GF M is significantly better than any other model. When the test compares the GFM with any other model, Voung’s statistics for the GF M is significant and positive. By comparing the Tobit model with the G Tobit model and the RF M with the GF M, we observe significant and positive values in the statistics, 27.930 and 37.728, respectively, so that we conclude that fixed costs are significantly different from zero. At the same time, by comparing the G Tobit model with the GFM, we also observe significant and positive values in the statistics, 2.446, so that incorporating disinvestment has a significant effect on the analysis of investment. In addition, OLS is significantly better than the Tobit model and the RF M, since Voung’s statistics is significant and negative for two cases. Therefore, the tests suggest that a partial specification of investment model, e.g., costly reversible investment or irreversible investment without fixed costs, is not appropriate to analyze actual investment behavior. Table 5.3 Model Selection for Computer and Office Equipment Industry F g \ G, OLS Tobit G Tobit RFM GFM OLS 0.9333 0.6808 0.5173 0.2483 Tobit -2.232*** 0.3748 1.0034 0.9351 G Tobit -0.429 27.930*** 1.1674 0.3820 RFM -1.776* 0.878 -0.855 0.7068 GFM 2.324“ 3.427*** 2.446*** 37.728*** Lower left: \éoung’s statistics, (NT)"” LR( - )/ a“) or 2 LR( - ); a positive value favors F 0 over ,. Upper right: sample variances of the log-likelihood ratio, a32 Parameters: net capital stock, 6: —0.005, A5: 0.01, and n = 1 *: reject H0 at 10 % **z reject Ho at 5 % ***: reject H0 at 1 % 57 iii. Test of Serial Correlation Table 5.4 shows the test of serial correlation for the computer and office equipment industry. The test with the TSE residuals and the GF M residuals fails to reject the no- serial-correlation hypothesis, while the test with the OLS residuals rejects the hypothesis at the five percent level. Therefore, the test of serial correlation also favors the GFM. The TSE residuals and the GFM residuals yield essentially the same probability for no serial correlation. In addition, the homoskedasticity case and the heteroskedasticity case yield very close probabilities for no serial correlation. Table 5.4 Serial Correlation Test for Computer and Office Equipment Industry V OLS Residuals TSE Residuals GF M Residuals Homoskedasticity t-stat. for r",_l = 2.063 t-stat. for f,_, = 0.565 t-stat. for r‘,_l = 0.584 Case Pr[ - ] = 0.044 Pr[ . ] = 0.574 m - ] = 0.562 Heteroskedasticity 2(7)-1)-SSR = 4.027 Z(T,--1)-SSR= 0.324 2(7)-1)-SSR = 0.345 386 Pr[ - ] = 0.045 Pr[ - ] = 0.569 Pr[ - ] = 0.557 Parameters: net capital stock, 5= —0.005, A6: 0.01, and n = 1 Number of data: OLS; 2 (T,- — 1) = 57, TSE and GFM; 2 (T,- — 1) = 53 (the difference is due to zero investment.) 5-2. Automobile Industry i. Estimation and Measure of Zero Investment Table 5.5 shows the measure of zero investment for the automobile industry. The case with net capital stock, 6 = —0.02, A5 = 0.01, and n = 2 (b), shows the best result according to the four criteria. Then, the measurement of investment for this analysis is Ln( K,,; / K, ) / 2 - 0.02. When the analysis uses gross capital stock, the program for analysis often fails to converge. 58 Agog—was mm H25 swap—:0 dmfi wee? a 3.0: 356508 030850 080m H® .309: owe-8:80 05 59> 03:09:00 ”Rom :08 21— :Omsom-cdéoz 3200.20 05 F 38$:me 8.0 «5:532: mo 308 coxwmcmufitm Suit ts +0,0 F125 mm 0 2 00 00002.8 8.0L?— ~0.0uE£ EN 00.0 00.0- $2 9 :00 Sam» $034 gala—.5 Sand—.5 00 0 0 00 STE; 00.855 0004-25 00.0%: «Surf 0 00.0 00.0 32 00.00",“ 020".» 00.003 00.0?3 SSnd 004mg; a. 0 S 00 00.808 "Ea ®nEE ®HEE ®uE£ _ 00.0 v0.0- 62 8 =00 0:0".4 00.8"3 ~20qu 00.00.15 00.0%.:— 00.0%?— S N o oo @035 moduacm @uEE modHEE @035 _ _od cod 82 00.003 :AfJ stun-N 00.00qu ESL-N 00.0n§.& 00.85: t. 0 0 00 RTE...— ©uE£ ®nEE 00.825 ®uEE a 80 ~00- 32 00.0?3 00:43 00.083 00.010 amend 00.0%.; 00.10.; 3. _ 2 00 3.01.5; 00.0“:E ©n:E @uEE ®uE£ 0 _00 00.0- oz 00.0004 00.00.13 00.83 NETS 00.00ué 00.85..— 00.85; S N 2 00 51:: ®uEa @u:E ®uE£ @uEa 0 00.0 00.0- 32 magma mnmmufi 2.00-:3 0.0.003 SEES 00 0 2 00 00.268 ©uE£ ©1200 _ _0.0 00.0- $2 3 000 8.3qu 03.304 :0 30 2: 300 Em 2.2 0000 o 0000. So 003 2 0 396 3am— .mo Hun—832 _OVOE mom-SOEOGOON .«o 0.5.0.82 950205 o_BoEo§80o oodumzhm cod-LEE mod-023m gala...— _ :3 «ed 0080 00 00.0 00.083 2 .00-0.3 00.0?3 Sawufi 00.00000 0 u .8 00 0 N 00 00.0.0500 2.0%.... 00.0%? 00.0uEi 5.0"5... _ 00.0 00.0 :05 00.0000 award 02-83 00.0000 Samud 00 0 S 3 00002.00 00.0uEa 00.0uEa A000 _00 00.0- 52 00 000 00.003 00.9.."5 00 m : 00 0802.00 Rana; 031:...— Aem ~00 3.0- 02 3 00.0 00.010 ans-"G 00 m 2 00 082,000 :85: 201:0.— 3: 00.0 00.0- 002 00 00 00.00.43 00.0?6 :0 30 2: .300 206 2.8 000.0 0 0000 30 003 3 0 000000 3mm— .«0 Span—Z ~35: motuoaocoom .«o 0.8—mac: 00.00000 0.0 0.00.0 61 Table 5.6 is the estimated coefficients of the best case that yields the highest likelihood. The sum of the estimated coefficients for 77,-,” 77K and 77...), is 0.029, and very close to zero. And, the log likelihood of the GF M exceeds the log likelihood of the second best model, OLS, by a margin of about seventeen. Fixed costs of investment and fixed costs of disinvestment seem to be of comparable size, since the estimated constant for v; is as large as the absolute value of the estimated constant for v; for the GF M. Those estimated constants are 0.301 and —0.367, respectively. Table 5.6 Estimation of Automobile Industry OLS Tobit G Tobit RFM GFM 27,-- 0.519(0.22) 0.597024) 0.128( 0.19) 0.563(029) 0.163( 0.17) :7.- 01010.03) 01120.03) -0.138( 0.03) 00990.03) -0.110( 0.02) 71-- 04170.27) 04810.29) 0.065( 0.24) -0.468(0.29) -0.024( 0.21) d1 (C) 01130.53) 01590.57) -1.060(26.81) -0.062(0.56) -0.621(28.16) d2(F) -0.146(0.59) -O.206(0.64) -1.180(26.81) -0.088(0.63) -0.687(28.16) d3(GM) -0.097(0.61) -0.l45(0.66) -1.143(26.81) -0.037(0.65) -0.662(28.16) 11:7 00000.01) 00000.01) -0.024( 5.77) 00000.01) 00000024) 0,: 7 N/A N/A N/A 0002000) 00020559) v,:_co'ns N/A N/A N/A 0.010(001) 0.490(39.78) V;: 7 N/A N/A 0015( 5.77) N/A 00070024) 5: _cons N/A N/A 0.457(26.80) N/A 030108.16) V1 - y N/A N/A N/A N/A 0.014(11.79) v1”: _cons N/A N/A N/A N/A -0.367(28.09) 0' 0.067(0.01) 0.071001) 0.046( 0.00) 0.071001) 0.046( 0.00) Pr[)Zn = 0] 0.984 0.954 0.239 0.935 0.507 Ln L,- 73.004 43.434 74.923 57.450 89.875 Standard errors in parentheses Parameters: net capital stock, 5: —0.02, A6= 0.01, n = 2 (b) Number of observations: total 57, investment 45, zero investment 3, disinvestment 9 62 ii. Test of Model Selection Table 5.7 shows Voung’s test of model selection for the automobile industry. Voung’s test of model selection ranks the five models as follows: GFM > OLS z G Tobit > RFM > Tobit. For the automobile industry, the generalized Tobit model is as good as OLS. Also, there are significant fixed costs of investment and disinvestment, since the GFM and the G Tobit model are better than the RPM and the Tobit model, respectively. And, because the GFM and the RF M are better than the G Tobit model and the Tobit model, respectively, disinvestment is important for analysis. Table 5.7 Model Selection for Automobile Industry F 9 \ G, OLS Tobit G Tobit RFM GFM OLS 0.8998 0.5576 0.8937 0.8283 Tobit -4.129*** 0.6821 0.7782 1.9468 G Tobit 0.340 62.978*** 0.7603 0.5120 RFM -2.179*** 2.104“ -2.654*** 0.9630 GFM 2.455*** 4.409*** 2.768*** 64.850*** Lower lefi: \éoung’s statistics, (1)/T)" 2 LR( - ) la“) or 2 LR( - ); a positive value favors F 9 over ,. Upper right: sample variances of the log-likelihood ratio, (:32 Parameters: net capital stock, 5: —0.02, A6: 0.01, and n = 2 (b) **z reject H0 at 5 % ***: reject H0 at 1 % iii. Test of Serial Correlation Table 5.8 shows the test of serial correlation for the automobile industry. The TSE residuals fail to reject the no-serial-correlation hypothesis at the ten percent level. The GFM residuals fail to reject the hypothesis at the six percent level. The OLS residuals reject the hypothesis. The homoskedastic case and the heteroskedastic case yield essentially the same probability for no serial correlation, similar to the other industries. 63 Table 5.8 Serial Correlation Test for Automobile Industry OLS Residuals TSE Residuals GF M Residuals Homoskedasticity t-stat. for f,_, = 2.648 g-stat. for f,_, = 1.675 t-stat. for f,_, = 1.902 Case Pr[-]=0.011 Pr[-]=0.101 Pr[-]=0.063 eteroskedasticity 2(T,-1)-SSR = 6.309 (T,-1)-SSR= 2.703 2(7)-l)-SSR = 3.430 386 r[-]=0.012 Pr[-]=0.1002 Pr[-]=0.064 Parameters: net capital stock, 6 = -0.02, A6 = 0.01, and n = 2 (b) Number of data: OLS; 2 (T,- — 1) = 54, TSE and GFM; 2 (T, — 1) = 48 (the difference is due to zero investment.) 5-3. Airline Industry Since there is an organized international used airplane market, it is easy for airline companies to resell their used planes, so the industry may have small fixed costs of disinvestment. The industry experienced a deregulation in the 1980’s. The Airline Deregulation Act of 1978 initiated this deregulation. Thus, this analysis includes a deregulation dmnmy variable, dereg (1 for years 21987, 0 for years <1987) in order to incorporate industry’s adjustments to the deregulation. Without this dummy variable, the econometric program that this analysis uses often fails to converge. The airline industry, however, shows results similar to the two industries and that there are significant fixed costs of investment and disinvestment. i. Estimation and Measure of Zero Investment Table 5.9 shows the measure of zero investment for the airline industry. The case with net capital stock, 5 = —0.05, A6 = 0.01, and n = 2 (b), shows the best result according to the four criteria. Thus, the measurement of investment for this analysis is Ln( KM / K, ) / 2 - 0.05. When the analysis uses the gross capital stock, the sum of the estimated coefficients for 77m, 77,, and 77,), is significantly different from zero, similar to the computer and office equipment industry. 64 553365 fl H35 swaofifi £me mac; 5 35: 356808 33838 oEom ”@ 4258 2:858 05 5:5 03:59:00 ”Rom :88 2..— c8§$§E>oZ 33320 05 3 ESE; 85 32582: mo mace vofificmnmmfm 8 1 4.55 2551:? 55515:. 8515:— mm 5 t 8 5551:: .3515...— 3.51:...— S51:E 351:...— _ 85 85.. 32 3.313 2.21.4 $5413 .6513 5215 555mm: av 2 cm cw 360:7.— Eén—zum owco>=oo owco>coo 360—2; g 5.0 86. 82 3313 8.21.5 35656": 8856.5 3.216 _ 85153 8515...— 8 v 2 on 251:...— ®1:E @135 @135 351:?— _ S5 85 “oz 381$ 9.5.1.4 3.313 3.313 581$ 55513: 55515..— wm m. t 8 E515...— =.51:F_ 351:3 351:5 351:?— _ S5 85- 562 2561.5 3.81.4 56.813 3513 3:125 8513..— 55515: S m om 8 851:5 5551:...— 54515; 851:? 351:...— : S5 85- .62 8.213 3.313 95513 «5.213 331$ 8515: 851:3 mm m «N 8 351:...— S51:F_ 551:...— 351:E 351:...— : S5 85- 62 3:13 8.81.4 55.13 3:13 8:154 8515: 55515: a. 5 mm 8 5551:...— 851:E «551:...— 85155 251:: _ S5 35- 62 53.1.3 321.5 85va 8513 8.81.5 85155 E 2. Q «N 8 $5155 851:3 551:...— 851:E 851:5 _ S5 85- 32 8.313 2.21.5 5:13 52.13 3.31.5 25135 2: 36.5 25 2.2 Echo 536.5 So 6.53 3 m 330 San— .wo 28:2 _ovoz motuoaoaoom mo 9:682 $5355 053$ €083.35 ccoN mo 03802 on 035,—. 65 5505:8558 55 ~25 3:05? 8&5 mac; 0 028 58068000 0088850 080m ”@ 50008 289800 08 :85 0353800 ”20m :58 EA 808005.585 Z 3053—0 05 3 852.5835 03 8080502: no 3500 @000 ”351??” 8 1 q..f5+.§51:5 555155 555155 05 m S 2. 50.5135 @155 555155 @135. @135 355 S5 35. 82 55.0515 55.00145 50.50145 5.1513 50.315 SAW—«Tm cc.efl_N_..m . 500.50 550mb mm m M: 05 85135 @135 £51.25 @135 @135 55 S5 8.5- $2 52515 55501.5 R5013 555513 52515 . 55.3.35 5551535 3 m 55 E 25155 @135 @155 @135 @135 355 S5 055- 82 R5515 8551.5 3.313 52513 5.1515 5551—25 85555 mm 5 2 2. @135 @135 @155 @1E5 @135 35 S5 555 62 555015 05.3.1.5 55.913 3.5515 55.5515 555155 2.5155 mm m E 05 @155 @135 @135 @135 @135 3a 85 Nod- 02 3.5015 55.9.1.4 8.913 2.213 55.315 53mg...— gum—$5 S 5 _5 05 @135 @135 @155 @135 @135 35 S5 35. 02 55.815 2 551.5 $55qu 55.5 13 :5516 555155 851.25 55 : : 55 5051.25 $51.25 £5135 85155 85155 5 555 555 82 5.605 55.213 35.53 05:13 55.3.15 55.51185 555155 2 5 2 55 555155 555155 S5135 25155 3.5135 _ 85 85- 02 55.5015 55.5516 05.5513 05.: _13 52515 . :5 35 2: 35 $50 $55 58.5 o 86... 5.5 53 55 5c 5556 San mo 538:2 E52 5.08.08ocoom .«o 0.8302 9.283 5.5 035.5 66 850558858 5_ 335 @0058 .835 wee? 5 08: 580508000 0088850 080m ”@ 40008 0808000 05 553 0385800 ”20m 3505 $5 80580518850 Z 88555—0 05 8 8.503885 08 808550558 .50 55500 0000351335 55 1 5.5 +5 255135 cm 3 9 N5 030800 080800 030800 8.01235 8.01235 3V m No.0 cod- 5.02 8 5555 3 5555 3 5555 5.55155 55.5516 55.5135 55.5135 _ 55 5 5 55 55.5135 @135 8.5135 @135 @135 305 _55 55.5 552 55.55155 55.55155 55.55155 55.55155 55.5516 . 55.5135 55.5135 55 5 5_ 55 55.5135 55.5135 55.5135 55.5135 55.5135 305 _55 55.5- 52 55.55.55 55555155 $5.53 5.55155 55.5515 55.5135 55.5135 55 5 55 55 55.5135 55.5125 5.5135 55.5135 55.5135 355 _55 55.5- 552 $5215 55.55125 55.55155 55.55155 55.55155 3 5 3 N5 0w50800 030800 030800 @1235 @1235 5.5V m 3.0 vod- 5.02 8 5555 2 5555 3 5255 55.5 155 55.5175 55.5135 55.5155 55 5 55 55 $5135 @135 55135 @135 @135 305 55.5 55.5- 32 3.55155 55.55155 55.55155 55.55155 55.5515 55.5135 55.5135 55 5 E 55 55.5135 135 55.5135 @135 @135 305 _55 55.5- 02 55.55155 55.5515 555.555 55.55155 55.55155 5551—555 5551—555 55 5 5: 55 55.5135 55.5135 55.5135 @135 @135 355 8.5 55.5- 82 55.55155 55.55155 55.55155 5.55155 55.5515 :0 0J 5 05 .555 2.50 255 555.5 0 5555 550 55 55580 889 .50 005832 _0002 5050808035 5 A .04 % .50 085502 50.5580 5.5 255.5 67 .anmemmE mm SHE :wsofi? .cwfi mac; n 26; 356508 33838 088 ”® .flovoE £68000 05 .23 0333800 ”20m 3on EA :ofiaomégo Z 32330 05 E “50¢?me 85 808635 .«o Shoo voxrainfitm 8 u 1: ts +.§£uE£ ”ES "55 "SE "Ea "E; "SE "SE Hn‘N ”.VN Hm‘N "HQ ”TN "Ea "5.5 "SE "Ea "Ea "35 "ES anN HYN Hm‘N HNQ "TN "55 "Ea "SE "SE "SE "SE "SE ”mg Hva "TN "N‘N Ill—N "Ea "Ea "Ea "Ea "Ea "Ea "Si anN HYN meN HQN "TN 8.335 San—NE 8 a m Nb SAVES 221:5 2.1:...— ooduEE ©uEE 3: 8d cod sz ”wanna 33nd 3.3mm 8.8%» 3.0an Edna...— Sana..— % m 2 R woduEa ooduEE Sana...— oodnswm 8.125 3: So So- «oz 38an Sans ”$qu 3.314 $.0an oodufiE 221%.— Nm m S N» Sous: 8.325 2.1:..— ooduEa 8.3%; 3: 3o 22. “oz vmwaufi Santa mmgnfi Sanka 2.6qu On 2 S as $5280 “@268 09263 00.0":th oodurtm 3v m mod mod- 82 8 8.3 9 BE 2 BE $.8qu whoaufi A: 2: 2: Bob E6 2: Boy 0 “Boy 30 a3 3 m 396 San .«o Moog—Z 352 motfiEocSm .«o 8382 6283 3 fig 68 .BuoE 28988 05 53> 03:82:50 ”20m 3on 2..— acmSom-§§o Z 32830 05 3 885:3,“ 03 308838 .«0 380 voxmmtmummtm 8 n ,8 +5 +.§5325 ”E5 “E5 325 325 325 325 325 "a“ "waN Hm‘N HNN ”TN 325 3M5 325 325 325 325 325 ”mg HYN ”TN HNQ "TN 325 #25 325 325 325 325 325 Hn‘N "3N "MN meN "TN 8.32.5 8.8nE5 8 v m 8 8.325 8.32.5 8.325 8.325 8.32.5 _ So 8.0 $55 8535 ~3an 2835 8.8qu 9:35 343.25 8.335 8 5 m 8 8.32.5 8.32.5 8.325 8.325 3.325 _ 88 8.0 3.86 8.8an Swans 8.83.5 8.85.5 GETS 8.325 88325 8 _ m 8 8.325 8.32.5 8.325 8.325 3.325 _ :8 8.0 380 gownfi S834 853a 8.854 213,5 8.325 oodufiE R o m 8 8.325 8.325 8.325 88325 5.8325 _ So 88 85 8.5an 85qu 8.5.35 $.8an afinfi 8.325 88.1.55 8 o m 8 8.325 8.325 8.325 8.325 8.325 _ So 88 $80 $234 3qu $535 8.8%» NEWS A: 2: A A: 38 250 255 Bose Bob 30 83 2 m 858 San mo “098:2 _ovoz motuoEOcoom mo 0.25502 85:82 2 035. 69 Table 5.10 shows the estimated coefficients of the best case with net capital stock, 6 = —0.05, A6= 0.01, and n = 2 (b). The sum of the estimated coefficients for 77R,” 77K and 77...), is —0.026, and very close to zero. And, the log likelihood of the GFM exceeds the log likelihood of the second best model, OLS, by a margin of about sixteen. Fixed costs of investment and fixed costs of disinvestment seem to be of comparable size, similar to the automobile industry. Those estimated coefficients for v; and v; are 0.417 and —0.389, respectively. Table 5.10 Estimation of Airline Industry OLS Tobit G Tobit RFM GFM m... -0.016(O.16) -0.047(O.18) 0.277( 0.16) -0.040(O.16) 0.245( 0.13) m: -0.108(0.05) -0.122(0.06) -0.099( 0.05) -0.108(0.06) -0.096( 0.04) 27..., -0.016(0.12) 0.013(0.14) -O.167( 0.13) -0.002(0.13) -0.175( 0.10) d1(AMR) 1.238(0.37) 1.411(0.44) -O.548(48.54) 1.373(039) -0.112(31.23) d2(DAL) 1.191(0.36) 1.311(0.43) -O.603(48.54) 1.278(O.38) -0.172(31.23) d3(UAL) 1.218(0.39) 1.351(045) -0.605(48.54) 1.308(0.40) -O.163(31.23) d4 (U) 1.151(0.33) 1.261(0.39) -O.474(48.54) 1.228(0.35) -0.100(31.23) dereg 0.046(0.04) 0.059(005) 0.003( 0.05) 0.048(0.05) 0.025( 0.04) .,,:y -0.008(0.00) -0.010(0.01) 0.002(20.26) -0.008(0.00) 0.001( 8.72) V1: y N/A N/A N/A 0.002(000) 0.006(20.20) vi:_cons N/A N/A N/A 0.012(0.01) 0.673(55.16) .4: 7 N/A N/A 0.004(2026) N/A 0.004( 8.72) v;: _cons N/A N/A 0.547(48.59) N/A 0.417(3123) 0;: 7 N/A N/A N/A N/A 0.0190 8.21) v; _cons N/A N/A N/A N/A -O.389(45.54) 0' 0.083(0.0l) 0.088(0.0l) 0.069( 0.01) 0.086(0.01) 0.064( 0.01) Pr[En = 0] 0.002 0.003 0.849 0.001 0.498 Ln L,- 81.545 40.702 68.770 66.292 97.547 Standard errors in parentheses Parameters: net capital stock, 6: —0.05, A6: 0.01, n = 2 (b) Number of observations: total 76, investment 55, zero investment 3, disinvestment 18 70 ii. Test of Model Selection Table 5.11 shows Voung’s test of model selection for the airline industry. Voung’s test of model selection ranks the five models as follows: GFM > OLS > G Tobit z RF M > Tobit. For the airline industry, the RFM is as good as the G Tobit. Otherwise, the order is the same as the other industries. There are significant fixed costs of investment and disinvestment contrary to expectations. Disinvestment is significant. Table 5.11 Model Selection for Airline Industry F 9 \ G, OLS Tobit G Tobit RFM GFM OLS 0.7572 0.6010 0.6515 0.4352 Tobit -5.384*** 0.2406 0.7450 1.1552 G Tobit -1.890* 56.135*** 0.8555 0.6732 RFM -2. 168* * 3.40.1 * * * -0.307 0.6415 GFM 2.783*** 6.067*** 4023*" 6252*“ Lower lefi: \éoung’s statistics, (NT)*'AZLR( - )/a‘) or 2 LR( - ); a positive value favors F 9 over r Upper right: sample variances of the log-likelihood ratio, (0’ Parameters: net capital stock, 5: -0.05, A6: 0.01, and n = 2 (b) y *: reject Ho at 10 % **: reject H0 at 5 % ***: reject Ho at 1 % iii. Test of Serial Correlation Table 5.12 shows the test of serial correlation for the airline industry. The TSE residuals and the GF M residuals fail to reject the no-serial-correlation hypothesis at the ten percent level, while the OLS residuals reject the hypothesis. The conclusion is the same as the other industries. The TSE residuals and the GF M residuals yield essentially the same probability for no serial correlation. The homoskedastic case and the heteroskedastic case also yield essentially the same probability for no serial correlation. 7l Table 5.12 Serial Correlation Test for Airline Industry OLS Residuals TSE Residuals GFM Residuals Homoskedasticity I-stat. for r',_l = 3.200 t-stat. for 73., = 1.138 t-stat. for f,_l = 1.153 Case Pr[ . ] = 0.002 Pr[ - ] = 0.259 Pr[ - ] = 0.253 Heteroskedasticity 2(7H)-SSR = 9.075 Z(T,~-l)—SSR= 1.289 2(T,~-1)-SSR = 1.324 Case Pr[ - ] = 0.003 Pr[ - ] = 0.256 Pr[ - 1 = 0.250 Parameters: net capital stock, 5: -0.05, A6 = 0.01, and n = 2 (b) Number of data: OLS; Z (T, - 1) = 72, TSE and GFM; 2 (T,- — 1) = 67 (the difference is due to zero investment.) 5-4. Summary E The empirical analysis investigates three industries: the computer and office equipment I. industry(SIC 3570), the automobile industry (SIC 3711), and the airline industry (SIC 4512). Although the choice of the industries is arbitrary, all of the examined industries show many similarities: the homogeneity of the economic indicator variable in the sales revenue, capital stock and the cost of flow inputs, the superiority of costly reversible investment with fixed costs or the corresponding GFM, no serial correlation in the GFM residuals as well as the TSE residuals, and reversible investment without fixed costs or corresponding OLS as the second best model. By comparing likelihood of the five investment models, the analysis concludes that fixed costs are significantly different from zero, and that incorporating disinvestment has significant effects on analysis. Also, as OLS is significantly better than the other models except the GF M and, possibly the G Tobit model, the analysis suggests that partial specification of investment, e.g., investment without the costly reversibility or fixed costs, is not appropriate to analyze actual investment. However, the estimated coefficients are different among the industries, which suggests heterogeneity among the industries. In addition, for the airline industry, the analysis requires the deregulation dummy variable so that the airline deregulation of the 72 1980’s could have affected industry’s investment. For the measure of investment, a net capital stock shows better results than the gross capital stock. The estimated depreciation rate is zero or negative for the examined industries, when the analysis uses the net capital stock. 73 CONCLUSIONS This analysis investigated costly reversible investment with fixed costs. The analysis applied option pricing theory to incorporate the impact of the possibility of future investment on current investment. Fixed costs of investment introduced minimum investment, while fixed costs of disinvestment introduced minimum disinvestment. Both If» fixed costs and the costly reversibility resulted in zero investment as the optimal choice. When the firm contemplated future investment, its investment was lower than when it did not. The analysis also investigated how the economic parameters such as the discount in" rate affected the critical values such as the target value and the trigger value of investment. As the theoretical model did not yield closed form solutions, this analysis resorted numerical solutions. More than 90,000 cases for investment with fixed costs and more than 30,000 cases for investment without fixed costs were examined, so that the conclusions were robust. All of the critical values, except the trigger value for investment with fixed costs, were linear in the parameters, while the target value for in vestrnent was semi-log linear in the parameters. The empirical analysis confirmed that actual investment behaved as the theoretical analysis predicted. The analysis examined three industries: the computer and office equipment industry, the automobile industry, and the airline industry. Although each industry had different estimated coefficients, they all showed the similar results: the homogeneity of the stochastic variable, the superiority of costly reversible investment with fixed costs or the corresponding GF M, reversible investment without fixed costs or corresponding OLS as the second best model, and no serial correlation in the GFM residuals. The analysis confirmed that there were the costly reversibility and fixed costs in actual investment. 74 APPENDICES 75 APPENDIX A TWO PERIOD MODEL OF COSTLY REVERSIBLE INVESTMENT WITHOUT FIXED COSTS This appendix solves the model as a two period model, and shows economic intuition of the model. The model regards future investment and disinvestment as a call option and a put option, respectively. The appendix shows that value of future investment as the call option is equal to the expected value of net gain from the second period investment while value of future disinvestment as the put option is equal to the expected value of net gain from future disinvestment. The appendix also shows that how first period capital stock affects the expectation of the second period gain. This two period model is a special case of Abel, Dixit, Eberly and Pindyck (abbreviated ADEP) (1996). They use a general form for the profit function, while this model uses the same profit function as the main text. There are no fiXed costs of investment in the appendix. There are three differences between this model and the model in ADEP (1996): In ADEP (1996) there is no physical depreciation, the purchase price of new capital is different between two periods,7 and the expected PDV of net cash flow includes costs of the first period investment.8 7 In the two period model, the derivative of the expected PDV of net cash flow will not reach the (second period) purchase price of capital in many cases. In such cases, the first period price of capital should be lower than the second period price of capital. This section assumes conditions under which the derivative of the expected PDV of net cash flow reaches higher than the second period price of capital. Therefore, the purchase price of capital can be the same for the two periods. 8 ADEP (1996) adopt the Net Present Value (NPV) rule, i.e., if the (expected) net present value, or the expected PDV of net cash flow less initial investment costs, is positive, the firm should invest. One consequence is a difference in the optimal investment rule. When the NPV rule is used, the derivative of the expected NPV, which is called q°, 76 A firm makes its first investment decision to choose optimally capital stock for the first period, Km, for a given level of capital stock, Kn, after the economic indicator at time t = 0, Z0, is revealed. Or, equivalently, the firm determines either d10 (= K0. — K0.) or 6le0 ( = K0. — K,,). At time t = A1, firm’s capital depreciates by the depreciation rate, 6, to its pre-investment level of capital stock, K .- = e'm Km). Then, after the economy reveals Z ., the firm makes its second investment decision to determine its post-investment capital stock, K ,.. The firm will not make any further investment after t = At. In addition, there are no fixed costs for both investment and disinvestment. Thus, we can rewrite equation (3) in the main text as follows: V(KO+9ZO): max EO[{4KK(§)+ fie-(”figbzi—ods — pkdlo + pli'dDoi {dl .dn} +e—Wi‘4nK16:fe—(yfierE—gd7_p;dll +pdeli] (45) subject to K0, = K,_ + d1O — dD0 , Kn; given, and K,, = K,_ +dI, —dD, (= e‘M’Km + d1, — dD, ). A-l. Investment Model First, we solve the second period investment decision. or the maximization of the second brace in equation (45). Assuming 7> #2, max E0[An K: fe‘(’+‘w)'Z:‘0dr—pidl, + p;.dD,] (46) {(11,111)} subject to K,, = K,_ + 611' —dD,(= e"‘WK0, + d1, —dD, ), K,_: given. Defining A, a fry/[(7 +619)—(1—6)(pz we; /2)J, y, a 21 /K,, , + yl E (p;( / A}, )l'il‘”), and y," a (p; / Ay)l"’“"), we can rewrite equation (46) as follows. should equal to zero, i.e., the optimal investment rule is q°=0. When the expected PDV of net cash flow is used, the derivative of the expected PDV of net cash flow, called q, should equal the purchase price of capital for investment or the resale price of capital for disinvestment if the firm invests or disinvests. 77 Av _ + _ 331375151? Z,I ”K3 —- pKdI, + pKdD, |Z,] (47) Its solution is o If Z 1 / K ,_ > yf , then the firm should buy new capital such that yl = yf , or d1 = (Z,/y;‘)—K,_. o If y,‘ S Z 1 / K ,_ S yf , then the firm should neither buy nor sell capital so that EA“ K 1+ = K ,_. :- 0 If ZI / K 1- < y," , then the firm should sell installed capital such that yI = y,‘ , or . dD=K,_ —(Z,/y;). L Here, yf and y,‘ are two critical values for the ratio, Zl / K .., in the second period. .. Then, after solving the first term in equation (45) and incorporating the above optimal investment for the second period, we can rewrite equation (45) as follows: V(K0+9ZO)= AnZI‘J—BK:+At '1 'I— A +e-W f A {jaw/<3 +PII'(K1— _K|+ )}dF(Zl|ZO) IKI— 6 A. +e—yAI [1:10- {jzil-oKli 'Pk(K1+ _Kl—)}dF(Z||ZO) — [K.. > K.-1p,:(1<.. - K,_ )+ [K,, < K0_1p;(KO- _ K0,) (48) Zl/yf,ifZI>y1+K1_ subject to K,, = K._ ,if ny._ ZZ, nyK._ Zl/yl-sifyl—Kl— >ZI- Here, F (Z 1 [Z 0) is the cumulative density function of Z . conditional on 20, Since K,_ is equal to e’aA'Ko. and appears in the limits of the definite integral in equation (48), the firm’s choice of capital stock in the first period affects not only the net cash flow for the 78 first period but also the expectation of net cash flow for the second period. This is how the first period decision and the second period decision are linked. A-2. Values of Future Investment and Disinvestment From equation (48), we can derive the value of future disinvestment as the put option, P(K0,Z0), and the value of future investment as the call option, C(K0,Zo) by comparing equation (48) with the so-called naive case in which the firm assumes zero second period investment when it makes its first period investment decision. By rewriting equation (48), we have the following equation. . A, V(Ko. , Z0 ) = 4.23;" K5181 + e-WM f 6; Z,‘"”K€.dF(Z. IZO) fin: -'|—K'~ Av 1—0 (9 — Av 1—0 9 — +3 I 921 K1+"PKK1+ — ‘5“21 K1—_pKKl- dF(Zl|ZO) —yAI Av 1-9 a + Av 1—0 0 + +e f“ 92, K,,—pKKH -— (92‘ K,_—pKK,_ dF(Z,|ZO) — [K.. > K..- 1p; (K... — K..- )+ [K.. < K8118; (K..- — K...) (49) =G(KO+,ZO)+e—WP(K0+,ZO)—e'rA’C(KO+,ZO) _[K0+ > Ko—lpk(K0+ " K0—)+[K0+ < KO— 1P; (Ko— _ Km) Here, . A G( . )-_- AKZ5’9KS: At +60%” 1" —8-"—Z,""1<{,’,aIF(Zl |Z0 ), (50a) 1‘ '.- A. _ _ A. _ _ p(.)___ f4 {Eh—Z" 9K: _ p1. [PE—[79— Z.‘ (21¢: _ pKKl_]}dF(Zl|ZO), (50b) and A, A, _ + C(')= [H 6" Z.':"Kr: _p’ZK'i'i—é—Z" ”K.‘i—p1,K1-]}dF(Z.1Zo)- (509) G( - ) is the PDV of the net cash flow for the so-called naive case. P( - ) is the value of future disinvestment as the put option. The first bracket of function P is the net 79 .. -—-_-. C"... cash flow from the capital stock after disinvestment, K... The second bracket of function P is the net cash flow from the capital stock before disinvestment, K 1-. Therefore, the brace as a whole is the net gain from second period disinvestment. If the economic indicator variable at the beginning of the second period, Z., is below the striking value, y,‘ K ,_ , the firm will disinvest. Otherwise, the firm will not disinvest so that the net gain is zero. Thus, function P is the expected net gain from second period disinvestment conditional upon information available at the beginning of the first period, Z0. Similarly, h if the economic indicator exceeds the striking price, y: K ,_ , the firm invests. Otherwise, the firm does not invest. Function C( - ) is equal to the expected net gain from second period investment conditional upon Z0, and the value of future investment as the call : '- w option. A-3. Optimal Investment for First Period The optimal decision for first period investment is to choose K,, to maximize V( - ). mimosa )1 (51) Equivalently, the optimal K0+ is determined from the derivatives of equation (49). 6V °K,,Z 2 =0 ‘1( 0 0)[ (3ij or. by defining N(K0+,ZO) = 6G(K0+,Z0 )/aK,, , q°(Ko. ,ZO ) = N(1<0.,Z0 )+ e—WP'(KO.,ZO)— e-WC'(K0..Z0 )- p; = 0 (52a) for investment, or q°(Ko. .20): N(Ko.,Z0)+ e‘WP'(K0.,Zo )— e“”"C'(K0.,Zo)— p1} = 0 (52b) for disinvestment. Letting At = 1, equations N( - ), P’(- ), and C '(- ) can be expressed as follows: N(-)= 4E 13"] , (53a) 80 Pi): 645 A; (yf)2_g(1—e‘2""’ 0+ +e_'i17ivl'['“(yiK0+/Z°)'5-(#z ”mm 0'2 + A, expl:(1— 6(gz — 6:? )—66] x {1_ ¢[ln(y,+1<.,./ZO)— {#2 - 5 — (9 — 1/2)afl]}[_20_]1_0. 02 K 0+ (53c) When the depreciation is assumed to be zero as in ADEP (1996), the first terms in P'( - ) and C '( - ), which are functions of K0. rather than Z0 / Km, vanish. Then, all of three functions become functions of Zn / K0,. By defining yo as Z0 / Km, and q(y(,) as N(yo) + e" {P'(y(,)-C'(y(,)}, equations (52a) and (52b) can be rewritten as q°(yo ) = {N(yo )- p}: }+ 6" {P'(yo )- C '(yo )i = 0, 0r (1(y0 ) = 19; (54a) for investment, and q°(yo)= {N (yo )- pk }+ e" {P'(yo )- C '(yo )i = 0. 0r q(yo ) = 19; (54b) for disinvestment. Figure A.1 shows the functions q(y), N(y), P'(y), and C '(y). In figure A.1, a dashed line shows the function N(y), which is concave and monotonically increasing. N(y) is the so-called naive case and the same as the derivative of the expected PDV of net cash flow for the second period since the firm will not make any investment decision after t = At. The function P'(y) appears as a convex function at the lower left comer. Its 81 y-intercept is close to but lower than p; ( = l), and it is monotonically decreasing and approaches zero. The function C'(y) appears as a concave function in the lower right part of the figure. It starts at the origin and remains close to zero until y approaches about 0.5. Then, it increases as y increases. the function q(y) starts at the P'(y)’s y-intercept, and moves horizontally to the right. Then, it moves along N(y), while P'(y) and CO») are close to zero. Finally, it moves away from N(y) and crosses the purchase price line ( p; = 2) from below. A bold part of q(y) is relevant to optimal investment. CHY) I‘ C' (y) Figure A.1 q(y), N(y) , P' (y), and C’ (y) for Two Period Model (6: 0.4, A”: 0.29., 6: 0, 7: 0.05, #2 = 0.02, 02 = #2, I); = 2, pl; : 1) 82 Because the firm anticipates high possibilities of future investment when the economy is booming, i.e., Z, is high, so is y, C '02) has higher values when y is high. On the other hand, when the economy is in slump, the firm contemplates disinvestment, so that P’(y) is high when 20 is low. As the physical deprecation is assumed zero, C’(y) is constant at zero for a low y, while P'(y) is constant at zero for a high y. When the depreciation rate is non-zero, C '(y) is constant at a positive level rather than zero for low y, while P'(y) is constant at a positive level lower than C '(y) for high y. Therefore, q(y) shifts right when depreciation exists. In other words, optimal capital stock is lower when there is depreciation than when there is no depreciation. Figures 12 and 13 show the optimal rule for investment and disinvestment, respectively. Optimal investment, given the purchase price of capital, p; , is the amount that makes Z0 / K0. equals y; , if Z0 / K0. exceeds y; . As figure A.2 shows, the function q moves apart from N0») before it reaches the purchase price line. The critical value for q(y), y; , is higher than the critical value for N(y), yf , so that given 20, the firm should invest less when it considers the possibility of future investment than when it does not. The optimal disinvestment rule is that the firm should disinvest by the amount that makes Z0 / K0. equal to yg , when ZO / K0. is below yg . Contrary to the optimal investment rule, as figure A.3 shows, q(y) and N(y) cross the resale price at the same point. In other words, the consideration of future disinvestment does not affect the optimal disinvestment decision in this case. 83 I ‘m‘u' ‘ Figure A.2 Optimal Rule for Investment in Two Period Model (yr z 0.497, and y; z 0.778) Figure A.3 Optimal Rule for Disinvestment in Two Period Model (y; z0.158. y; ~0.158) 84 APPENDIX B APPROXIMATION OF G SATISFYING J(R,G) = 0 This appendix derives the approximation of G satisfying J(R,G) = 0. J(R, G) a R h(G)— G'"”h(G" )= 0 (55) Here, 0* satisfies J(R,G) = 0, given R. B-l. Approximation by Order of Exponents This section derives an approximation by choosing a greater term from two terms in either the denominator or the numerator in equations g(x) and 1 — g(x). Since G > 1 and ¢N~ Gm h(G)=———1——{1—-1—:2}, and h(G")=—1——{1—1—_—6}. f(1-9) ¢~ f(1-<9) 4),, Thus. equation (55) can be approximately written as :G§1’\‘-l+0z 0, 1-g(G—l)z 1, R (D,.—1+9— 0"” (pp—1+6 f(1-9) m f(1-9) 90,» By rewriting equation (56), we have Ga: z [[M][&)R:ll_o . (57) ¢P " 1 + 6 (PM B-2. Approximation by Binomial Series = 0. (56) The Binomial series is (1”). =1+¢x+¢(¢-1)x2 +¢(¢-1X¢-2)x3 + 2! 3! ... (5 8) z1+¢x. Then, G"’" z1+¢,,(G—1), G"”z1+(1—6XG—l), G‘“ z1+¢,,(G—1), G“"’" z1—¢,.(G—1). G‘W zl—(l—OXG—l), and G""’“ z1—¢,,,(G—1). Therefore, Gm. TC“ ”((01) ’(oN XG-l), Gm —Gl-0 z (901’ -1+9XG—1)’ 0"" -G"’“ ”(l-B-(pNXG-I), 0"” -G“”"’ shop +¢~XG-1), G""’" —G-'+” z(—go,, +1—6XG-1), and G“ —G"”" z(—1+6+¢NXG—1). Thus, .— 1—0— _ g(G)zfl——1:€ ~g(G"), and 1—g(G)z——-——fl z 1 —g(G '), and (Pr- N ¢l’—¢N — .— — 1—6— 6 _ f(1-6) (0N (Pr "‘ (0N (PP (PP '(DN Asaresult, 86 R —G""= 0. (59) By rewriting equation (59), we have 0" z RH) . (60) B-3. Refinement of Approximation Figure B] shows approximation of G* by equations (57) and (60), as well as the approximation proposed by Abel and Eberly (1996) and exact G*. Abel and Eberly suggest I G*~l+ 60'3 3(R 1)" 61 ~ (1-6)(y+6) _. H ( ) Figure B] Approximation of G* (1) ( a: 0.4. 5: 0.06, 7: 0.051,;12 = 0.05, oz = 0.02) 87 Equation (57) seems a better fit, although 6* by equation (57) is not equal to unity at R = 1. By adding an auxiliary term to equate G“ to 1 at R = 1, we have I l G*~ M £1; R W- (AV-1+6 (0" l_6+1 (62) (pp-1+6 ¢N (D,.-1+9 (0N ’ l _ 147) or 0* z [MKQJM — 1)+1 . (63) (pp -1+ 9 cm. Figure B.2 shows 6* by equations (62) and (63) as well exact 6*. Equation (63) is a better fit than equation (62). Equation (63) is equation (16) in the main text. Figure B.2 Approximation of G* (2) ( 6: 0.4, a: 0.06, y: 0.051, #2 = 0.05. oz = 0.02) 88 APPENDIX C FUNCTION q WITH AND WITHOUT FIXED COSTS AND RANGE OF INACTION This appendix discusses the coefficients of the function q, B,» and EN. In particular, this E‘ appendix shows 8,, < B; < 0 < Bi, < BN and y], < y‘ < y+ < y}, , where an asterisk (*) indicates investment with fixed costs. C-l. Coefficients of Function q, BN and Bp The function q is written as follows: q = Hy” + BNyq" + B,.y"’". (64) H>0, BN>0, BP1 Because of fixed costs, there are a triangular area below the resale price line and a crescent area above the purchase price line for the function q’ withfixed costs. On the other hand, the function q without fixed costs are tangential to those price lines. Therefore, the fimction q' with fixed costs is below the function q without fixed costs for small y, while the function q' is above the fimction q for large y. In other words, q —- q. > 0 for small y, while q — q' < O for large y. The difference, q — q. , can be written as follows: q — q’ = (B. - 31);)“: + (13,. - 3;. )y:" . (65) Since (0N < 0 and (0,. > 1, the first term of equation (65) dominates for small y, while the second term of equation (65) dominates for large y. Therefore, BN — BR, > O to move the local minimum of the function q below the resale price line, and Bp — B}. < 0 to move the 89 local maximum of the function q above the purchase price line. Thus, the coefficients of the function q has the following relationship. 13,, < 3;, < 0 < 3;. < 13,, (66) C-2. Range of Inaction The function q first moves downward, then turns upward, and, moves downward again, as y increases from zero. And, the boundary conditions for investment without fixed costs is q'(y)l= (1— 6)Hy"’ + <0~B~y"" “ + (pl-BM“ J= 0 at y“ and y*. (67) Therefore, the derivative of q changes its sign from negative to positive to negative at the critical values, y‘ and y’ . As a result, q’(y) is strictly positive for the range of inaction, ( y“ , y" ). The derivative of the function q' has the following relationship with the function q. q‘ '6) - q'ty) =60~ (3;. — 3., )y. " + q» (3;. — 3,, )y“"" > 0 fory > 0 (68) At y" and y‘ , q. '02) > 0, since q'(y) = 0. Therefore, the positive slope of the function q' is wider than that of the function q. In other words, by defining ' yg and y; at which the function q' has the local minimum and the local maximum, respectively, we have y; < y“ < y+ < y; since the slope of the function q' is strictly positive between y’ and y+ . As a result, when investment has fixed costs, the local minimum for the function q moves to the left and down, while the local maximum for the function q moves to the right and upward. At the same time, at y}, and y}, , the function q. is negatively sloped. Therefore, y}, < yg < y; < y;,. Thus, we have y}, < y' < y* < y;,. In other words, the range of inaction for investment with fixed costs, ( y}, , y}, ), is wider than the inaction range without fixed costs, ( y+ , y" ). 90 APPENDIX D Serially Correlated Error This appendix discusses a serially correlated error in the econometric models, and Voung’s test of model selection is revised in accordance with a serial correlation assumption. This appendix assumes that an error is an AR(1) process, i.e., u, = pu,_. + v, , where v, ~ i.i.d. N[O, a“2 ]. Discussion focuses on the OF M and OLS and concludes that the GFM is still better than OLS. D-l. Voung’s Test of Model Selection With the serially correlated error, the likelihood function for the GFM becomes the following. L[u,|X, ,z,,n',vg]= n _1_¢[Lpfi] X H[ OLS > G. Tobit > RFM > Tobit. However, there is one exception, which is the G. Tobit model vs the RFM in the airline F“ industry. Even though this case has an opposite sign, the difference between the two E competing models is statistically insignificant. In addition, OLS is as good as the GFM t4. 4... Table D2 Model Selection under Serially Correlated Error 1. Computer and Office Equipment Industry F9 \ G, OLS Tobit G. Tobit RFM GFM OLS 1.1887 0.7705 0.7095 0.2570 Tobit -2.062** 0.3553 1.1618 0.9699 G. Tobit -0.616 26.451 ** * 1.2263 0.4262 RFM -1.501 0.913 -0.654 0.6586 GFM 1.795* 3.207*** 2.223" 33.691*** 2. Automobile Industry F0 \ G, OLS Tobit G. Tobit RFM GFM OLS 1.2654 0.5495 0.9537 0.6463 Tobit -3.885*** 0.6726 1.1400 1.8953 G. Tobit -0.410 61.396*** 0.7479 0.4882 RFM ~2.186** 2.094" -2.117** 0.7542 GFM 2.212“ 4.466*** 2.980*"‘* 59.085*** 3. Airline Industry F9 \ G, OLS Tobit G. Tobit RFM GFM OLS 0.8462 0.5286 0.6315 0.3999 Tobit -5.594* ** 0.2626 0.8686 1.2781 G. Tobit -3.458*** 45.893*** 0.8517 0.6338 RFM -2.186** 3.658*** 0.841 0.6545 GFM 1.401 5.336*** 4.271*** 45.741*** Lower lefi: 2> the airline industry > the computer and office equipment industry. And, OLS ranks the estimated p as: the airline industry > the automobile industry > the computer industry. These results are consistent with the test of serial correlation in the main test. Table D.4 shows the Durbin-Watson (D-W)statistic for the OLS residuals. The D-W statistic is based upon the OLS residuals. The computer and office equipment industry shows the highest statistic, while the airline industry shows the lowest statistic. All of the three industries reject the no-serial-correlation hypothesis at five percent, since their D-W statistic is lower the corresponding critical value, d), 5 9,. The results are also compatible with the test of serial correlation. Table D.3 Estimated Coefficient of AR(1) Process, ,0 Industry OLS Tobit G. Tobit RFM GFM Computer 0.2826 0.2915 0.1822 0.2854 0.0781 Automobile 0.5086 0.4918 0.2776 0.5042 0.3129 Airline 0.5563 0.5813 0.2255 0.5693 0.2514 Table D.4 Durbin-Watson Statistic for OLS Residuals IndUStry D'W StatiStic kl, n d,“ 5% d“. 5% Computer 1.3527 6, 60 1.372 1.808 Automobile 0.9778 6, 57 1.334 1.814 Airline 0.8491 8, 76 1.399 1.867 94 D-3. Discussion Even though this appendix incorporates serial correlation in error into the analysis, the GFM is still likely to be the best among the five models. The GFM residuals seem to be serially uncorrelated. On the other hand, OLS residuals seem to be serially correlated. In addition, OLS with serial correlation could be as good as the GF M when we look at the airline industry. However, there is one reason to conclude that OLS is biased and the GFM is better than OLS. Figure D] is a schematic diagram for comparison of the GFM with OLS. In figure D. l , solid lines represent the GFM, while a broken line represents OLS. As figure D.1 shows, OLS overestimates investment, while it underestimates disinvestment. At the same time, Ln(Z, / K,) is assumed to be an arithmetic Brownian motion, or a unit root process, so that, when it is high, it remains high for a while. Since the OF M is assumed to be consistent, observations are located around the GFM, and each GFM residual is either negative or positive regardless of Ln(Z, / K,). On the other hand, when an OLS residualiis negative for high Ln(Z, / K,), the next OLS residual is likely to be negative because Ln(Z, / K,) likely remains high due to the unit root process. Thus, the OLS residuals are likely to remain negative as long as Ln(Z, / K.) is high. Therefore, the OLS residuals are serially correlated with positive p, while the GF M residuals are serially uncorrelated. ’/ 019/ /’ 0 LnG‘ ——————————— 7”— ’ I o ——————— r—o~éo—| GFM / LnG' —————— l/ : I( I /'I I / I l (D) I (O) I (I) Lnyér LnYi-r Ln (Zt/Kt-) Figure D.1 GFM vs OLS 95 APPENDIX E TWO STEP ESTIMATION FOR LIMITED DEPENDENT VARIABLE MODEL In order to conduct the test of serial correlation, we estimate the limited dependent variable model by a two step estimation (TSE). This section shows its estimates. For comparison, the GFM estimates are reported in the same functional form. Both estimates seem to be close to each other. For non-limited observations such as investment observations, k,, their expected value, E [k, |x, , z, ,k, > 0], is written as the following. E[k,|x, ,z, ,k, > 0] = z,v; + x,77 — z,.,,m.v_, + Elu, > —(z,v; + x,77 — z,.,,,,,.v., )J ¢[(le; + x!" _ ZIJchf) 01 (Dl(z,v; + x,77 — zhmv, )/0'J = z,v; + x,q — z,',,,,cv, + ovi[(z,v; + x,77 e z,.,,,,,.v, )/0'] (71) + : Zlvg +x177-Zumcvf +0 Here, (15 and (D are the p.d.f. and the c.d.f. of the standard normal distribution, respectively, and [1(-)(E ¢(-)/