. - ‘ .A: :‘ ', J-.v.“.. - .IhLIL éul::‘ ! .: z : H l 5. ‘.. ,1 -.J Y I'I‘t‘r " u V ‘ . . fig“. “W ' Randy 1: W33 1 ' 1211.2». :13 ' ‘ 3'r41':24"'3 - ' I JE‘iW'm‘ 'i-b, ‘ pmaf § "1.” . . n -:n :3] “Nu .‘ ' " L' “z". V_F- a. v -... _,...¢.. l\‘-"V-‘ . - w..—--- -—-~l-— 5- ' I a.‘ “NW": ‘.. 3.2}; u «r >1»!an ‘ b :31 -..- "a." V a ‘ ; - . _ .V ,“f - r: '1 . . r .‘ . .... . w .. _. .» . ' . ' w" ‘ _ .u. ; - A m... - - v _._.... L.’ W.-.” . n... .‘ “5:1 “wily...“ ‘ mm... thm‘fm 5:: I.-v.-u " “ 2 . . a a. . ' - _; '~ ‘ ‘. . m. I v' u v D A ' ' . W, .L. . . ’u‘n _ u . u ». m. .m I ' I ‘ '. , i“_:’£ '. " ‘ . “j 9' ‘2'“; ‘v in: V1 ‘ «1?§§i{§1f*' 1m: ,z 4* ‘ 5:143‘ 7 In. fl . :44:- F . 1.1-44— . . A . 1 ': ”mw .. avg-:3. . _ -‘ .. .rz. 3:3:— * "u. up“. . v» ,.-u-m ‘0.— .nth‘ ”3.. v . .£ . '1‘ "'3’1' W33,” ' J I.’ . n ' WA 1' I“ l: H ! 1222*:21W: Lb” ‘ ‘ r z}! [’1 .. w-u 11‘ a i- In “Em ‘ IN.'~Z'T.E‘.‘:;:'1:';W it": $3?“ -: ZZZ-'3' 1&'"'." 1:25 wnvfitfi‘ A 3m: mama». 1"“ "E" - ‘ , n‘.‘ I: l ._ .. _ . 9:: -n‘fl‘-P’. - "‘“m u“. at: w u. I: ”a." a. m - .‘uw..., _ 4‘ " «a... w r--.» .m- “- ~ kg A .- V A w, )fi . ‘ . I I. A . . a... -..L..“..m.~ “.9“? “A . ”W W... “1.. :-~ . a. '3 A . ahlh I y. . .u‘ . 7'!"- -.‘ 'qu F‘ v *3. 'L' - 1. 1.: ,._.,_.-. . ,.. .4. y-.‘.’ Q ..,I.- "L — “-1....4 I ~mwup~ v‘ v.,-- t—- . .. .- » - .. ,_-‘p.--—r H. I:"¥”": ‘ l. >_. .—--.r——-. .~ .0...”- -- .9 .1 . . puln". . “-9— . :- ".4 t .' up . -, 119'! . ‘J :M, H}; -~ ~ \ m.,..... -._.--'r y». "w...” 60."- a _.‘ .. _.,___ . =25 up“ .. ‘gzur.’ y. . I} ; :1.‘ : —... ..- . . -3?» . wag. $3 . .— A “w... Aw4.- .‘X', ‘4 [if I V ‘ pififlullfv ‘ | : \ ‘ 4 . Hr 0' . < .14 o.‘~.-3. v—ow-é-wn m - ._ .. .. .4,“ .... .4._‘ 1g! ’. u _' l & , I v . V :g_ :3. L -1331 — 1945315 , lilllllllllllllllllllllHlllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllll :2 302080 6091 2 V 0 , LIBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled CONTRACT THEORY AND ITS APPLICATION TO CROWNDWATER MARKETS IN INDIA presented by Kei Kajisa has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph. D. degree in Agricultural Economics W Major p'rofessor [/0 / $3797 Date MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINE return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE m: i % 29°} am 1 5 2003 Eflgtifl 11/00 c/CIRCIDateDuepss-m4 CONTRACT THEORY AND ITS APPLICATION TO GROWNDWATER MARKETS IN INDIA By Kei Kajisa A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Agricultural Economics 1999 ABSTRACT CONTRACT THEORY AND ITS APPLICATION TO GROWNDWATER MARKETS IN INDIA By Kei Kajisa This dissertation explores the mechanisms of contract choice and price determination under bilateral transaction between an owner of irrigation systems and a non-owner at groundwater markets. A sample of owners and non-owners in six villages in Madhya Pradesh in India is used for empirical analysis. The analyses of contract choice show that risk-sharing is the factor underlying the choice of sharecrop contract over either fixed- rent or flat-charge contract. The analyses of price determination show that the unit water price becomes higher under sharecrop contract since the water buyers pay a risk premium to the sellers when risk is transferred from the buyers to the sellers by sharecrop contract. The other notable result of price analyses is that in contrast to the conventional notion of seller’s monopolistic pricing, the market structure rather works in favor of the buyers in that they are charged no greater than the cost of irrigation. Thus, the water markets in the study area are described such that while the water prices are not exploitative, in risky environment sharecrop contract is chosen with a payment of a risk premium from the buyers to their sellers. C0pyright by Kei Kajisa 1 999 To my parents iv ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would first and foremost like to express my gratitude and sincere appreciation to my major professor Thomas Reardon for his unwavering support, guidance and encouragement. I would also like to thank Dr. Takeshi Sakurai, who allowed me to join his research project, for having the patience and generosity to guide me through entire process of the research project beginning from designing the questionnaire, conducting a field survey, to analyzing corrected data. I remain indebted the other members of my committee, Professors John Strauss, Allan Schmid and Scott Swinton, given that I have benefited enormously from their erudition. I also acknowledge funding this study from the Global Study Program through the National Institute for Environment Studies, Tsukuba, Japan and partially from the National Research Institute of Agricultural Economics, Tokyo Japan. This paper would not have been possible without the collaboration with faculty members and their associates of the Indian Institute of Forest Management: P. Bhattacharya, Sangeeta Chourasia, Shailendra Das, Debashis Debnath, Neeta Dubey, Hilaluddin, K. Krishna Kumar, Shailes Kumar, Ram Prasad, Kalpna Rawat. I am gratefully acknowledge to my friends at Michigan State University, especially Nazmul Chaudhury, Janet Owens, and Takashi Yamano who are the comrades in a workshop which is informally organized by ourselves to discuss issues of development economics. Lastly, I would like to especially thank to my parents and dedicate this work to them. TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ........................................................................................................... viii LIST OF FIGURES ........................................................................................................... ix INTRODUCTION ............................................................................................................... 1 CHAPTER 1 CHARACTERISTICS OF GROWNDWATER MARKETS IN SURVEY AREA ............ 3 CHAPTER 2 CONTRACT CHOICE AT GROWNDWATER MARKETS ............................................ 8 2.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................... 8 2.2 Methodological Issues ............................................................................................ 10 2.3 Variable Construction and The Hypotheses ........................................................... 11 Household Wealth ............................................................................................... 12 Management Ability ........................................................................................... 13 Monitoring Cost .................................................................................................. 15 Remarks on Flat Charge Contract ....................................................................... 18 2.4 Econometric Results ............................................................................................... 19 Comparison ofThree Types of Contract ....................................... 19 Comparison between Sharecrop and Non-sharecrop Contracts .......................... 20 2.5 Village-level Determinants ..................................................................................... 21 2.6 Concluding Remarks and Policy Implication ......................................................... 23 CHAPTER 3 PRICE DETERMINATION UNDER BILATERAL TRANSACTION ........................... 30 3.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................. 30 3.2 Structure of Water Markets in the Survey Area ...................................................... 32 Monopoly Power ................................................................................................. 32 Individual Price Variations ................................................................................. 33 3.3 The Model ............................................................................................................... 35 3.4 Variable Construction ............................................................................................. 40 3.5 Regression Results .................................................................................................. 44 Market Structure ................................................................................................. 44 Determinants of Unit Water Price ....................................................................... 46 3.6 Concluding Remarks and policy Implications ................................................................. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION .................................................................................. 56 APPENDIX A REVIEW OF LITERATURE ON CONTRACT CHOICEAT LAND RENTAL MARKETS ........................................................................................................................ 59 Risk-sharing Model ....................................................................................................... 59 vi Limited Liability Model ................................................................................................ 60 Screening Model ........................................................................................................... 61 Double-incentive Model ............................................................................................... 62 Monitoring Cost Model ................................................................................................. 64 APPENDIX B SUPPLAMETNARY TABLE FOR CHAPTER 2 ............................................................ 68 APPENDIX C CALCULATION OF THE WATER-CHARGE-COST RATIO AND THE RETURN TO IRRIGATION INVESTMENT .......................................................................................... 69 APPENDIX D THE QUESTIONNAIRE ................................................................................................... 71 BIBLIOGRAPHY .............................................................................................................. 92 vii LIST OF TABLES 1-1 Characteristics of Irrigation in six Villages ................................................................... 7 1-2 Types of Water Contract across Villages ...................................................................... 7 2-1 Descriptive Statistics of Variables ............................................................................... 26 2-2 Multinomial-logit Regression Analysis of Determinants of Contract Choice ............ 27 2-3 Logit Regression Analysis of Determinants of Contract Choice ................................ 28 2-4 Types of Water Contract and Selected Characteristics Across Villages ..................... 29 3-1 Ratio of Water Charge to Irrigation Cost and return to Capital Investment in Different Case Studies ....................................................................................................................... 52 3-2 Price Variations within and across Villages by Types of Input Goods ....................... 53 3-3 Descriptive Statistics of Variables ............................................................................... 54 3-4 OLS Regression Analysis of Determinants of Unit Water Price ................................. 55 B-l MultinomiaI-logit Regression Analysis of Determinants of contract Choice (Constrained Models) ......................................................................................................... 68 C-1 The Water-charge-cost Ratio and the Rate of Return to Irrigation Investment .......... 69 viii LIST OF FIGURES A-l Transaction Cost and Optimal Contract Choice ......................................................... 67 ix INTRODUCTION Incompleteness and imperfection of markets are salient features in less developed economies. Some markets such as credit and contingent markets are missing, and thus an opportunity of transactions may be limited. Asymmetric information gives considerable scope for all kinds of opportunistic behavior such as cheating, shirking, and moral hazard. Consequently, transaction costs associated with the use of markets for exchange may become very high and sometimes prohibitive.l In response to these circumstances, exchanges may be limited to a face-to-face informal contract as opposed to the open market transaction. The most famous example in agrarian economies is the existence of various arrangements of land-tenancy and labor-employment contracts (Hayami and Otsuka, 1993; Bardhan, 1989, 1984). Unfortunately, however, it is not well known how similar informal contracts are observed for groundwater markets between owners of private irrigation systems and non-owners. As well as land tenancy, the transactions of groundwater markets carry interesting features which we cannot observe under perfectly competitive markets (Saleth, 1998; Meinzen-Dick, 1996; Fujita and Hossain, 1995; Kahnert and Levine, 1994; Janakarajan, 1993; Shah, 1993; Pant, 1991). First, different types of contracts coexist. Second, variations in water price are very large not only across villages but also across individual pairs of owners and non-owners. These two characteristics of groundwater markets provide us with an opportunity to tackle the long- standing research issues in the field of the economics of contracts: what are the economic ' Transaction costs typically involve the cost of information, search, negotiation, screening, monitoring, coordination, and enforcement. factors underling the choice of a particular type of contract; what are the determinants of price under informal contracts. Yet, the groundwater markets have not systematically been analyzed within the framework of contract theory. The research objective of this paper is to explore theoretically and empirically the mechanism of contract choice and price determination of groundwater markets. The theoretical argument in this work is based on the economics of contracts. For empirical study, I use our original data set from India. India provides an interesting case because private irrigation systems have been rapidly proliferating since the cut back of public investment in large scale canals in the late-19605, and consequently ground water markets have been emerging in many villages (Rosegrant, 1997). I begin with an analysis of contract choice in the following chapter; chapter 4 explores water price determination under different types of informal contracts; chapter 5 synthesizes the previous chapters' conclusions and policy implications. Chapter 1 CHARACTERISTICS OF GROWMDWATER MARKETS IN SURVERY AREA The six villages chosen for this study are located in two adjacent districts, Hoshangabad and Narshimhapur, in Madhya Pradesh. In these villages, a research project on an integrated analysis of natural resource management was conducted from December 1997 to April 1988. The number of water buyers in each village is not so large since most of the farmers own tubewells (Table 1-1). Among 569 households in the surveyed villages, there are 41 water sellers and 79 water buyers (Table 1-1). The number of sellers is smaller than the number of buyers since some sellers sell water to multiple buyers. We also confrrmed who sells to whom in order that the samples became matched data set. The surveyed villages are homogeneous in terms of agronomic condition. The climate is characterized as monsoon with deep-black soil.2 The farmers in the area cultivate soybeans during rainy season (Kharif) without relying on irrigation, and they cultivate mostly wheat and sometimes chickpeas with electric pumps and tubewell irrigation systems during dry season (Rabi).3 The household samples I use in this study are 26 sellers and 38 buyers who cultivate wheat. All water sellers are self-cultivators using their own tubewells, and there is no pure-seller who owns tubewells but do not farm by himself. Sellers are usually sell water after meeting the needs of their own fields, and thus it is claimed that sellers are selling 2 There is no major difference in terms of annual rainfall, but it increases gradually as we move from west to east. 3 Sugarcane is cultivated through a year but it is the minor activity in the study villages. “surplus” water (Shah, 1993). All tubewells for irrigation are powered by electric pump and there is no diesel pump in our survey field. By the government policy the electric charge is free in village A, B and C. In village D, E, and F, if pump is smaller than 5 horsepower the well owners can use electricity for free, but if larger, the well owners have to pay fixed amount of electricity charge by season. All the buyers are also self cultivators and thus there is no specific case in the sample wherein the landlords provide water to the tenants as a part of interlinked land tenancy. In villages A, D, E and F, some farmers who do not own tubewells irrigate their land by water from stream (Table 1-1). Among 38 water buyers, there is no buyers who answered that they would irrigate their land by stream if current seller refused to sell water, but 8 buyers answered that they would buy water from another tubewell owner, and 30 buyers answered they have no water source other than the current seller. This indicates that easiness of water access varies among buyers. Although a wide variety of contracts exist in Indian water markets, the contracts we observed in the study area are classified into three: sharecrop, fixed-rent, and flat- charge contract.4 Under sharecrop contract, buyers and sellers share buyers' harvest for water charge; under fixed-rent contract, water-buyers pay a fixed amount of cash for certain acreage of irrigation for a season; under flat-charge contract, the buyers can ‘ Besides these three types of contracts, Shah (1993) observes several different types in Andra Pradesh in India. First is labor contract under which the buyer provide labor and draft power to the seller in return for water. Second is crop and input sharing contract under which the seller provides water, and shares buyer’s input costs and the harvest (interlinked contract). Fujita and Hossain (1995) observed the contract called “chaunia” in Bangladesh under which the well-owner rents in land during dry season from the landlord who does not own irrigation systems. We observe no such contracts as those observed by Shah; there is only one case in our data set which resembles a "chaum‘a" contract. irrigate as much as they want at a given per-acre-water—price.5 Although each contract is observed 17 %, 13 % and 8 % respectively over the study area, distribution of three types of contracts in each village is skewed (Table 1-2). We observe all three types only in village C and D. I talk about the methodological issue caused by this in next chapter. In order to clarify the terms of contract, I have a few remarks on linkages of water contract with other inputs. First, all water buyers cultivate their own land, and thus there is no specific case in our sample wherein the landlords provide water to the tenants as a part of interlinked land tenancy. Second, there might exist linkages with other inputs such as animal, tractor or labor. Water buyers might rent capital inputs (animal or tractor) from sellers, or buyers might provide labor works to sellers as a part of payment. Unfortunately I do not have this kind of information in our data set. In our sample, however, the farmers pay village- homogeneous rental fee to capital inputs, and village-homogeneous daily-wages to hired labors. Thus, even if buyers use seller's animal or provide labor works to sellers, there seems not to be interlinked with water transaction. As for seed, fertilizer and pesticide, all sample households purchase them at either public or private store, and thus there is no possibility of interlinked contract through these inputs. Third, there are several cases in our sample wherein sellers do not allow buyers to operate irrigation systems (pump transportation, pump driving, and channel digging). The salient feature of these cases is that all these sellers also do not handle their irrigation systems by themselves but hire an irrigation manager who conducts all irrigation activities. Since these hired managers are also in charge of buyers' irrigation operations, 5 A unit of measurement is the area irrigated. This is common in the area where farmers use electric pumps, and electricity is provided for free or fixed amount payment per season, while hourly payment is buyers do not operate irrigation systems by themselves. I discuss about this in next chapter. common for diesel pumps since diesel consumption is linked to hours of operation. Table l-1: Characteristics of irrigation in six villages A Number of ag household Number of well-owner- cum-non-sellers Number of well-owner- cum-water-sellers Number of water buyers Number of households irrigated by stream Irrigated agricultural households (%) 70 40 71% Village C D 93 100 74 49 7 8 12 1 5 O 18 100% 90% 560 311 41 79 41 83% Table 1-2: Types of Water Contract across Villages A Total Number of Contract Observed in Village (3) Sharecrop (2) Fixed-rent (3) F lat-charge l l 0 Village C D 3 4 6 1 2 2 17 (45%) 13 (34%) 8 (21%) Village total 11 7 38 Chapter 2 CONTRACT CHOICE AT GROWNDWAER MARKETS 2.1 Introduction It is well known that there exist variety types of contracts for land tenancy all over the world. A number of researchers have theoretically and empirically investigated the relevant economic factors underlying the choice of a particular type of contract over others.6 Unfortunately, however, the same amount of effort has not been devoted to the analysis of the contractual choice for groundwater markets, despite the existence of different forms of contracts. Moreover, few studies pay attention to the uniqueness of groundwater market contracts A unique phenomenon at groundwater markets is that we observe not only sharecrop and fixed-rent contracts but also flat-charge contract under which water fee is charged either hourly basis or acreage basis, and payment is done when water buyers use irrigation systems (Saleth, 1998; Meinzen-Dick, 1996; Shah, 1993). Different from land, un-bulky input like irrigation water can be sold according to volume. Still a certain portion of sellers and buyers choose fixed-rent payment. There may exist economic reasons underlying the choice of flat-charge contract over fixed-rent contract. On the 6 For review of theoretical achievements, see Hayami and Otsuka (1993) and Singh (1989). For econometric empirical works on contract choice at land rental markets, see Tunali (1993), Allen and Lueck (1992), Rozenzweig (1988), Datta et. al. (1986), Alston et. al. (1984). For descriptive empirical works, see Sharma and Dreze (1996), Roumasset and Uy (1987), Robertson (1982), Bliss and Stern (1982), R30 (1971) other hand, two contracts can be practically indifferent if rescheduling of fixed-rent contract is allowed when unexpected events happen after they enter into the contract. In this regard, the issues of contract choice at groundwater markets are not only an identification of the determinants but also a clarification of the reasons of existence of flat-charge contract. Yet these issues have not been addressed systematically considering the past theoretical achievement of contract choice, nor adequately tested by data from water markets. The purpose of this paper is to explore the mechanisms of contract choice among sharecrop, fixed-rent and flat-charge contracts at groundwater markets for a sample of wheat-cultivating water sellers and buyers in six villages in Madhya Pradesh, India. Recent theoretical treatments regard an incidence of a particular type of contract is a response to risk, limited access to contingent market, input market imperfections, asymmetries in information (Hayami and Otsuka, 1993; Singh, 1989). I examine whether these factors significantly affect farmers' contractual choice among three options, especially between fixed-rent and flat-charge contracts. The sample I use has a notable advantage for this purpose; I can match water sellers and buyers, so that I can observe both parties' characteristics. Thus, my econometric results do not suffer the omitted variable problem which is due to using only one party's characteristics in an analysis of two parties' choice problem. Section 2.2 is devoted to the empirical strategy; Section 2.3 presents variable construction and hypotheses; Section 2.4 and 2.5 present analytical results quantitatively and qualitatively; Section 2.6 highlights the main conclusion and suggests relevant policy implications. 2.2 Methodological Issues An empirical strategy commonly used for multiple choices is either the ordered logit or the multinomial logit model. According to the "agricultural ladder" argument, sharecrop contract should be ranked lower than fixed-rent contract since sharecroppers are regarded as more dependent on their renter in terms of agricultural management (Hayami and Otsuka, 1993; Spillman, 1919). While this argument is widely accepted in literature on land tenancy, we are not sure a priori where we can rank flat-charge contract which is not observed in land tenancy. Thus, I use multinomial logit model for choice among three types of contracts in this paper. I also perform likelihood ratio test in order to check whether fixed-rent and flat-charge contracts are statistically indifferent, and then if so, I conduct logit analysis for choices between sharecrop contract versus fixed-rent and flat-charge contracts. Another feature of the empirical strategy in this paper is that I include characteristics of both sellers and buyers as explanatory variables. Since choice of contract involves both parties, my econometric results suffer less from the bias caused by problems associated with omitted variables than the empirical literature in the past that uses either sellers' or buyers' characteristics alone. The last is about treatment on village-fixed effects. Much of contractual difference is undoubtedly due to complexity of historical, sociological, and political factors peculiar to different places. These factors are difficult to be observed and thus usually assmned to be captured by village dummies in cross-section analysis. Unfortunately, however, as we mentioned in chapter 1, due to zero incidence of a 10 particular type of contract in several villages in our data set, I have to give up using village dummies in my econometric analysis. The omission of village dummies would result in potential bias in estimates, even if the six villages are located in agriculturally homogeneous area. For compensation of this shortcoming, I also provide descriptive analysis in section 2.5, where I investigate the relationship between dominant contract forms in the villages and village level characteristics. 2.3 Variable Construction and The Hypotheses In this section I list covariates I use in this paper and hypothesize them based on the models presented in the literature on contract choice (for the detail of each model, see Appendix A). However, flat-charge contract is not discussed there simply because land tenancy contract is the literature's main interest and there is no flat-charge in land tenancy contracts. Hence, I first review how tenancy literature discusses the choice between sharecrop and fixed-rent, and then make remarks on peculiar character of flat-charge contract at the end of this section. I divide covariats into variables that attempt to measure household wealth, management ability, alternative opportunity, and factor related with moral hazard. The descriptive statistics of covariates are presented in Table 2-1. 11 Household Wealth Wealth plays an important roll in two fundamental models of contract choice: , risk-sharing and limited liability models. The former recognize contract as a risk-sharing device in environments characterized by missing contingent markets and asymmetries in information (Stiglitz, 1974). Sharecrop contract has benefit of transferring risk from buyers to sellers, while it could cause the Marshallian inefficiency problem. On the other hand, fixed-rent contract let buyers shoulder the entire risk without Marshallian inefficiency problem. Given this tradeoff, benefit from sharecrop contract would become bigger as buyers get more sensitive to the risk and sellers get more willing to bear some of it. Assuming risk-averse is decreasing in wealth, the larger the buyers' wealth, the more likely is the buyers to shoulder the risk and thus the more likely fixed-rent contract is to be chosen, whereas the converse holds for seller's wealth. Limited liability explains the relationship between wealth and contract choice in a different way (Sengputa, 1997; Basu, 1992; Shetty, 1988). Due to non-existence of contingent markets in an agrarian economy, liability of buyers' payment is limited by their initial wealth. Sellers will know that the default on fixed-rent may occur when the harvest fails and buyers are poor, while the possibility of complete default is lessened by sharing the harvest. Hence, for buyers with large wealth, fixed-rent contract would be more likely to be chosen.7 Meanwhile, sellers' wealth does not matter in this argmnent since sellers are receivers of the payment. The wealth-variables I use in my empirical analysis are buyers' and sellers' last year's animal holdings (the number of oxen plus cows) and total land holdings (acre). These variables may not be truly treated as exogenous because farmers adjust these 12 variables in their long term decision process. However, they can be still treated as “quasi”—exogenous for cross-section estimation process. Land holdings are seldom adjusted. The last year’s ntunber is given to the current year activity, although the number of current year's animal is a part of the entire production decision. Management Ability I use management ability in my regression for three reasons. First, the risk- sharing argument supports the inclusion of this variable. Management ability is considered to be closely related with vulnerability toward risk in production. The agent can make the risky environment less risky if he has the management ability. Thus, the higher buyers' (sellers') ability is, the less likely buyers (sellers) hesitate to shoulder the risk by fixed-rent contract (by sharecrop contract), resulting in getting positive (negative) sign on buyers' (sellers') ability variables for the choice of fixed-rent over sharecrop contract. Second, importance of managerial inputs in contract choice is also pointed out by Eswarn and Kotwal (1985). It has been noted that resource owners often provide managerial inputs to sharecroppers, while fixed-rent farmers are more independent in terms of their farm management. If water buyers have little experience in irrigation agriculture, they would expect suggestion from water sellers who have longer experience of irrigation agriculture and know better about their irrigation systems. On the other hand, if buyers are already experienced, they would rather choose fixed-rent contract to manage their cultivation by themselves. Thus, the higher the buyers' ability, the smaller the benefit from sharecrop contract, while the larger the sellers' ability, the larger the 7 This hypothesis holds without assuming risk-averse agents (see review in Appendix 2 for the detail). 13 benefit of receiving their managerial input through sharecrop contract. The other way round, I predict positive (negative) sign on buyers' (sellers') ability variables for the choice of fixed-rent over sharecrop contract. Third, the model called screening model claims that sellers can design a menu of contracts such that high ability buyers will prefer fixed-rent contract and low ability buyers will prefer sharecrop contract (N ewbery and Stiglitz, 1979; Hallagan, 1978). Sellers have incentive to do this since they cannot directly observe buyers’ true ability and since buyers might mimic themselves as low ability in order to be charged low prices. Thus, buyers' management ability would be positively correlated with the incidence of fixed-rent contract, while sellers' management ability does not matter in this argument. The model is, however, criticized that the ability is generally revealed sooner or later in small rural community (Singh, 1989; Eswarn and Kotwal, 1985). Thus, the sign on buyers' ability variable may not be explained by this logic. There is also difficulty in empirical procedure since true ability is very difficult to measure correctly. One way to circumvent this problem is to find a good proxy, but if good proxy exists, sellers screen buyers by that but not by a menu of contracts, (so that sellers do not have to propose the menu of different types of contracts). Nevertheless, the sign hypothesized by this model does not conflict with those derived from previous two explanations, and thus my prediction does not change. The management ability variables I use are buyers' and sellers' schooling years and age of household head, which are assumed to measure managerial knowledge and experience. Arguably, these variables are not current year's choice variable. 14 Monitoring Cost Monitoring cost is inevitable when there is asymmetry of information between sellers and buyers and thus there is a possibility of cheating in production activities (Allan and Lueck, 1995, 1992; Roumasset and Uy, 1987; Datta et. al., 1986; Alston et. al., 1984). For example, labor-effort must be monitored if there is an incentive to Shirk; usage of irrigation systems must be monitored if there is an incentive to overuse them; sharing the harvest also must be monitored if there is a possibility of underreporting. A number of researchers claim that monitoring of these activities is costly and that a particular type of contract is chosen to minimize the sum of these monitoring costs. Under sharecrop contract, if monitoring of buyers' labor-effort is very difficult, buyers put less labor-effort than the optimal since they receive a portion of their marginal products (the Marshallian inefficiency). On the other hand, since the entire harvest is obtained by buyers, fixed-rent contract entails no cheating in labor-effort. Hence, given other things being equal, the more costly it is to monitor labor-effort, the more likely a fixed-rent contract is offered. Moreover, the more labor-intensive crop cultivation is, the larger the potential losses from cheating, and thus the more likely fixed-rent contract is to be chosen. Sharecrop contract, however, has advantage in reducing the possibility of buyer’s overuse of irrigation systems since increment of outputs achieved by overuse must be shared with sellers. Meanwhile, under fixed-rent contract buyers may overuse sellers’ irrigation systems since the entire harvest goes to buyers. Thus, the more difficult to monitor irrigation overuse, the less likely fixed-rent contract is to be chosen. Sellers 15 would be concerned about buyers' overuse if their irrigation systems are vulnerable and precious. Thus, the larger the potential damages on irrigation systems, the less likely fixed-rent contract is to be chosen.8 The variables related with monitoring in our data set are the total amount of investment to irrigation systems, whether seller and buyer belong to the same caste group, whether a buyer has alternative water seller, and whether buyers operate irrigation systems by themselves.9 Regarding the amount of investment, the more expensive the systems, the larger the potential damages by buyers’ overuse, resulting in low possibility of fixed-rent contract. The dummy for caste matching has multiple effects. If both parties belong to the same caste group, it might be easier to build trust between them. Buyers’ overuse of sellers’ irrigation systems is less likely to occur, resulting in high possibility of fixed rent contract. Meanwhile, cheating in labor-effort may be also less likely to occur within the same group, and thus fixed-rent is less likely to be chosen. Hence, the sign on this variable is an empirical question. The dummy for existence of alternative water seller may or may not have effect on buyers’ cheating activities. The buyer who has alternative seller may have larger incentive to do cheating activities since he can go to another seller in case of rejection from current seller afier a disclosure of his cheating activities. If so, this dummy, which is related both with labor-effort shirking and irrigation overuse, has multiple effects as 8 Monitoring the harvest-sharing arouses cost, too. Buyers know exact amount and quality of their harvest since they harvest by themselves, but sellers have to guess it. If the cost of physical measurement and division of harvested crop is very high, buyers would have incentive to underreport their harvest to the sellers. Thus, the more costly the harvest sharing, the more likely fixed-rent contract is to be chosen. Since I use the samples of wheat cultivator, difficulty of measurement does not vary across samples. Thus, we do not discuss the monitoring cost aroused by harvest-sharing. 16 caste matching dummy does. In a small village, however, loosing reputation would reduce the opportunity of transactions with other villagers. The buyer may not do cheating activities regardless of the existence of alternative seller. Thus, the empirical question is whether this dummy becomes significant or not, and if significant, how the existence of alternative buyer effect incentive of cheating and then contract choice. I also allow for dummy whether buyers’ irrigation operation is conducted by the irrigation manager who is hired by sellers. If so, sellers do not have to worry about buyers' overuse of their irrigation systems even under fixed-rent contract. Hence, this dummy may have positive sign for the choice of fixed-rent over sharecrop contract. However, as I mentioned in chapter 1, managers operate buyers’ irrigation only when sellers hire managers for sellers' own irrigation activities. Moreover, there is neither the case such that sellers themselves operate inigation systems for buyers nor the case such that sellers hire someone just for buyers irrigation operation, which would have been observed if sellers just wanted to reduce the possibility of irrigation overuse by buyers. Hence, the variation of this dummy may not due to the reason claimed by monitoring cost model but probably due to management inertia, resulting probably in undeterministic sign on this dummy. Before concluding this subsection, it is better to mention about potentiality of the endogenous variable problem of the dummy for hired irrigation manager. Since this is a part of production decision, estimates would be biased. Given limited information in our data set, however, I can neither adequately address the nature of potential bias in the parameter estimates due to this problem, nor can I adequately instrument these 9 Total investment to irrigation systems consists of the cost of well digging, electric pump, and sprinkler systems. 17 endogenous variables. Alternatively, I run regressions without these dummies to see robustness of the results. Remarks on F lat-charge Contract There are differences and similarities between fixed-rent and flat-charge contract. The most remarkable difference is the nature of risk each party faces. Sellers receive certain amount of payment from buyers for sure under fixed-rent contract, while under flat-charge contract sellers may not be sure since buyers can stop buying water from him in the middle of the season if they get enough amount of irrigation water by rain. Thus, sellers also face the risk, but the nature of that risk is different from the one transferred from buyers to sellers under sharecrop contract which depends on buyers production outcomes but not on buyers decisions about buying or not buying. Therefore, flat-charge contract may have different coefficient on the household wealth and management ability which are assumed to be related with the attitude toward risk. Besides, seller will not worry about buyers' default (limited liability) under flat-charge contract since payment is done when buyers use irrigation systems. This may also change the coefficient on buyers' wealth. The structure of monitoring cost does not vary between fixed-rent and flat-charge contract. Under either contract, buyers have incentive to overuse irrigation system unless detected, while there is no possibility of cheating of labor-effort. Thus, coefficient on the variables related with monitoring cost may not be different. Furthermore, there seems to be no practical differences between two contracts. In land tenancy contract, it is observed that landlords reschedule fixed-rent contract when 18 ll unexpected events happen (Ishikawa, 1975). If the amount of fixed-rent can be rescheduled according to the actual frequency of water application, fixed-rent contract becomes akin to flat-charge contract. Sellers and buyers would not strictly distinguish two contracts. Therefore I have no clear-cut hypothesis as to flat-charge contract, but have empirical question of whether fixed-rent and flat-charge are practically different, and if so how wealth and ability variables have different effect on the choice of fixed-rent over flat-charge contract. 2.4 Econometric Results Comparison of Three Types of Contract The results of multinomial logit analysis on three types of contracts are given in Table 2-2. The comparison group is sharecrop contract. Model 1 is without dummy for hired manager and Model 2 is with it. I perform the likelihood ratio tests to examine whether all coefficients are equal across fixed-rent and flat-charge contracts (x2 statistics and associated p-values are in the table). The null hypotheses is that all coefficients across fixed-rent and flat-charge are same but different from sharecrop contract. The test results indicate that I cannot reject the null hypotheses at any acceptable significant level (p-values are 0.43 and 0.49).lo Given these test results, I should not call the difference between fixed-rent and flat-charge significant. As I talked in the previous section, sellers and buyers in our study area do not practically distinguish the two contracts. They 19 probably answered the closest option between fixed-rent and flat-charge, while the actual payment schedule may be more flexible depending on contingent events. Meanwhile, the farmers still distinguish sharecrop from non-sharecrop contracts. I discuss this issue in next subsection. Comparison between sharecrop and non-sharecrop contract I combine samples of fixed-rent and flat-charge contract into one group. The results of logit regression analysis on choice of fixed-rent and flat-charge contracts over sharecrop contract are given in Table 2-3. Since the qualitative results are not altered dramatically between Models 1 and 2, I will confirm my discussion to the model with the dummy for hired manager. The variables significant at 10% level are seller’s animal holdings and schooling years which have negative effect on the choice of fixed-rent and flat-charge contracts, consistent with my conjecture from risk-sharing model and division of managerial input. Allen and Lueck (1992, 1995) claim that empirical evidences do not support risk-sharing model. However, their argument is based on the data from the United States of America and mainly from non-agricultural sectors where contingent markets are relatively better organized and people are more tolerant to risk than any agrarian economies in less developed countries. My results tell us that risk-sharing can still be a motivation of choosing a particular type of contract in agrarian economy in developing countries. On the other hand, the limited liability model is not supported by our data since the effect ’0 First, I run multinomial logit regressions with the constraint such that null hypothesis is true (see Appendix B for the results). Then, likelihood ratio statistics are calculated from unconstrained and constrained results. 20 from buyer 's wealth is statistically very weak. This is probably because the possibility of complete default at water markets can be circumvented by flat-charge contract. The factors affecting monitoring cost do not have very strong statistical relationship. Thus, cheating activities in terms of labor effort and irrigation overuse are not serious problems in a small community where people know each other and reputation plays important role in transaction. The statistical relationship of manager dummy is also very weak, implying that the reason of managers' operation for buyers is just due to management inertia. 2.5 Village-level Determinants I will explore qualitatively the village-level determinants underlying contractual choice. The village-level effects would be clearly recognized by focusing on two extremes, namely the villages B and E where only fixed-rent-and-flat-charge contracts or sharecrop contract exists in large (Table 2-4). The village characteristics I use are weather shock, credit access, remoteness, and health condition presented from rows 4 to 10 in Table 2-4. The weather shock is measured by the number of drought in the last ten years, district-level means and standard deviations of rainfall from 1901 to 1950. The remarkable feature is that weather shock is harsher for the village B than for the village E. The village B had experienced droughts, having lower mean and higher standard deviation of rainfall (rows 4, 5, and 6). However, the village B seems to be reckless of 21 this climatic risk as nobody chooses sharecrop contract. One potential reason is that all sample farmers are irrigated and thus are not vulnerable to weather shock. Another potential reason is the existence of well-firnctioning credit and asset markets for consumption smoothing. In drought years, the suffered farmers in the village B either borrowed money or sold their asset to compensate their losses (not shown in Table 2-4). As for credit markets, they claimed that 90 percent of villagers have access to formal credit in the village B (row 7 in Table 2-4). On the other hand, only 47 percent of the villagers have access to formal credit in the village E, implying that means of relief are very limited. In general, the accessibility to the means of relief is also measured by the remoteness of the village. The remoteness, which is measured by distance from the block headquarter (row 8), distance from the nearest agricultural market (row 9), and accessibility to vehicles (row 10), tells us that the village E is not only located the farthest from the block headquarter but also seasonally limited to the access to vehicles. While the village B is not the least remote village, the stretch to the city is not so long since it still has access to vehicles all seasons. In sum, while the village B faces risks in agricultural production due to unstable weather condition, their annual income would be rather stable since they have access to several means of relief such as credit and asset markets. One the other hand, the village E faces limited access to the means of income smoothing. Therefore, it is natural to conjecture that the village-level factors associated with risks have significant effects on contractual choice. Thus, omission of village dummies in regression analysis would cause the omitted variable problem; all coefficients might be biased. Nevertheless, it is 22 consistent with village-level explanation in this section that the risk covariates in regression analysis (i.e. relative animal holdings and schooling years) have strong statistical relationship with contractual choice. Getting individual and village level analysis together, what I can still insist is that risk-sharing motivation is significantly affecting contractual choice. 2.6 Concluding Remarks and Policy Implications In this paper, I explore the factors underlying the contractual choice at the groundwater markets for a sample of wheat-cultivating water sellers and buyers in the six villages in Madhya Pradesh, India. In the study area we observe three types of contracts: sharecrop, fixed-rent, and flat-charge contracts. A notable feature of water markets is the existence of flat-charge contract which is not used for land tenancy. However, a flexibility of informal contractual agreement in agrarian economy makes us wonder whether the villagers practically distinguish flat-charge and fixed-rent contracts. The results from multinomial logit regression analysis show that there is no statistical difference in the choice between flat-charge and fixed-rent contracts. This is probably because it is allowed to reschedule fixed-rent payment according to the actual frequency of irrigation. Unfortunately, our data set does not have the information on contractual rearrangement; further detailed investigation of this issue would be required. Meanwhile, the results’obviously show that the farmers distinguish sharecrop contract and non- sharecrop contracts. 23 The logit regression analyses are conducted to quantify the determinants underlying the choice between these two options. Given the availability of variables, the explanations I employ are risk-sharing, limited liability, managerial input sharing, screening, and monitoring cost models. Putting individual-level econometric analysis and village-level qualitative analysis together, what I can safely state is that risk-sharing is among the motives of choosing sharecrop contract in the study area. While Allen and Lueck (1992, 1995) rejected risk-sharing motivation by using the data from United States of America, it is still an important determinant of contract choice in developing countries where contingent markets are not adequately developed. The econometric analysis shows that sharecrop is more likely to be chosen when sellers own animals (i.e. being less risk- averse), and when sellers are educated (i.e. having risk management ability). The village- level analysis shows that sharecrop contract is skewed in the village that faces limited access to means of income smoothing. Given imperfection of contingent markets and asymmetries in inforrnaion, sharecrop contract is a "locally optimal" outcome. However, since there may exist the Marshallian inefficiency problem under sharecrop contract, the "local optimum" does not necessarily correspond with the " global optimum" which could have been achieved under perfect markets and no asymmetries in information. The empirical literature on land tenancy shows the existence of inefficiency under sharecrop contract in India (Shaban, 1987; Bell, 1977). If there exists the Marshallian inefficiency also at groundwater markets under sharecrop contract, policy makers had better to consider how to reduce the production risk in villages and also to increase access to means of risk hedge. Further detailed investigation of production environment and detection of inefficiency would help 24 guide policy makers in designing appropriate strategies to obtain "global optimum" at groundwater markets in Indian villages. 25 Table 2-1: Descriptive Statistics of Variables Variable Mean Standard Deviation Household Wealth Buyer's last year's animal holdings 2.26 1.81 Seller's last year's animal holdings 3.13 1.66 Buyer's land holdings (acres) 5 .07 4.79 Seller’s land holdings (acres) 9.63 9.95 Management Ability Buyer’s schooling years 5.58 4.99 Seller's schooling years 4.32 4.29 Buyer's age 44.42 11.01 Seller's age 45.97 15.04 Factor related with Moral Hazard Total amount of investment (000Rs.) 6.08 3.87 Caste matching dummy 0.61 0.50 Existence of alternative seller (dummy) 0.24 0.43 Hired manager dummy 0.11 0.31 26 Table 2-2: Multinomial-logit Regression Analysis of Determinants of Contract Choice (The comparison group is sharecrop contract) With Hired manager dummy Without Hired manager dummy Fixed-rent Flat-charge Fixed-rent F lat-charge_ Household Wealth Buyer's animals 0.112 -0.090 0.066 -0.155 (0.34) (0.19) (0.19) (0.32) Seller's animals -1.113 -1.627 -l.214 -1.658 (1.37) (1.77) (1.38) (1.74) Buyer’s land holdings 0.096 0.025 0.097 0.015 (0.60) (0.1 I) (0.58) (0.06) Seller's land holdings 0.152 0.208 0.137 0.190 (1.17) (1.31) (1.02) (1.20) Management Ability Buyer's schooling 0.032 -0.088 0.038 —0.107 (0.24) (0.50) (0.28) (0.58) Seller's schooling -0.307 -0.214 -0.365 -0.190 (1.56) (0.78) (1.58) (0.60) Buyer's age -0.075 -0.075 -0.055 -0.069 (1.22) (0.86) (0.86) (0.70) Seller's age -0.001 0.065 -0.001 0.072 (0.01) (0.83) (0.01) (0.87) Factor related with Moral Hazard Total investment -0.1 14 -0.469 -0.085 -0.449 (0.47) (1.51) (0.34) (1.40) Cast matching dummy 2.088 5.360 1.598 5.010 . (0.87) (1.94) ‘ (0.65) (1.82) Alternative seller dummy 2.603 4.371 2.601 4.171 (1.02) (1.51) (1.03) (1.47) Hired manager dummy . . 1.872 0.748 (0.96) (0.27) Constant 4.217 1.901 3 .854 1.892 (1.01) (0.35) (0.93) (0.33) Likelihood ratio test :3 statistics 11.12 11.49 (l-Io: coefficients are same) [0.43] [0.49] Observations 38 38 x2 statistics 30.78 31.81 [0.10] [0.13] Pesudo R2 0.38 0.39 flLikelihood -24.69 -24.17 The comparison group is sharecrop contract Numbers in parentheses are absolute value of z-statistics. Numbers in brackets are p- values. "‘ significant at 10% level; ** significant at 5% level, *** significant at 1% level 27 Table 2-3: Logit Regression Analysis of Determinants of Contract Choice (1 if non-sharecrop (i.e. fixed-rent or flat-charge) is chosen) Without hired manager With hired manager dummy dummy Household Wealth Buyer's animals 0.078 0.047 (0.25) (0.15) Seller's animals -1.304 -1.299 (1.73)‘ (l .69)* Buyer's land holdings 0.070 0.077 (0.47) (0.50) Seller's land holdings 0.180 0.159 (1.42) (1.26) Management Ability Buyer's schooling -0.003 —0.001 (0.03) (0.01) Seller's schooling -0.297 -0.330 (1.65)‘ (1.68)"' Buyer's age -0.076 -0.057 (1.31) (0.93) Seller's age 0.018 0.016 (0.33) (0.29) Factor A fleeting Monitoring Cost Total investment -0.244 -0.204 (1.08) (0.90) Caste matching dummy 3.315 2.823 (1.44) (1.23) Alternative seller dummy 3.443 3.461 (1.37) (1.44) Hired manager dummy . 1.444 (0.83) Constant 4.405 3.808 (1.1 1) (0.96) Observations 38 38 X’statistics 19.66 20.41 [0.050] [0.060] Pesudo R2 0.38 0.39 Log Likelihood -16.30 -15.92 Numbers in parentheses are absolute value of z—statistics. Numbers in brackets are p- values. "' significant at 10% level; ** significant at 5% level, *** significant at 1% level 28 Table 24: Types of Water Contract and Selected Characteristics Across Villages Village A B C D E F Total Number of Contract Observed in Village (3) Sharecrop l 0 3 4 9 0 17 (45%) (2) Fixed-rent l 3 6 1 0 2 13 (34%) (3) Flat-charge 0 4 2 2 0 0 8 (21%) Weather Shock (4) Number of drought in the l 3 l 0 0 0 - last ten years (5) Mean of rainfall (mm/year) ' 1295 1295 1295 1361 1361 1361 - (6) Standard Deviation of 297 297 297 217 217 217 - rainfall (mm/year) ‘ Access to Credit (7) Percentage of villagers who 100 90 100 95 47 25 - can access to formal credit b Remoteness (8) Distance from block 30 25 4 13 50 17 - headquarter (km.) (9) Distance from the nearest 30 30 4 12 13 17 - agricultural market (km.) (10) Accessibility to Vehicles 8" a" all a" seasonal All - $085011 season $685011 season . $685011 Notes a District data b Formal credit institutes includes commercial bank, cooperative bank, governmental bank. 29 Chapter 3 PRICE DETERMINATION UNDER BILATERAL TRANSACTION 3.1 Introduction In South Asian countries including India, private lift irrigation systems, i.e. wells, pumps and water conveyance networks, have been rapidly proliferating since the cutback of public investment of large scale canals in the late-19605 (Rosegrant, 1997). Consequently, groundwater markets are emerging in villages, and we observe informal but repeated water transactions between LIS owners and non-owners. In India, the area irrigated through water markets is estimated to be reaching nearly 50 percent of gross irrigated area with LIS, making significant contribution to increasing agricultural production (Shah, 1993). There has been concern, however, about water sellers' exploitative pricing behavior toward water buyers, which stems from the conventional wisdom of treating water sellers as "water-lords" (Bagchi, 1995; Campbell, 1995; Kahnert and Levine, 1994; Pant, 1992; Dhawan, 1988). In response to this concern, a number of researchers have investigated the relationship between sellers and buyers at groundwater markets, and they have also addressed the factors underlying high water prices. Most of the case studies on these issues has been in terms of village-level comparisons. A consensus that has emerged from these case studies suggests that the water sellers' pricing behavior is not necessarily monopolistic, but rather depends on village-level factors such as depth of 30 water table, rainfall pattern, energy source, and density of wells (Shah and Ballabh, 1997; Fujita and Hossain, 1995; Shah, 1993). At the same time, noticing price variations within villages, several articles have emphasized the effect of individual characteristics of sellers and buyers on price, albeit the statistical evidences is limited (Saleth, 1998; Meinzen- Dick, 1996; Janakarajan, 1993; Pant, 1991). In fact, as I talk later, in small agrarian communities where both sellers and buyers know each other and usually have some forms of personal relations, they often complete exchange through a face-to-face transaction as opposed to an open-market transaction. Furthermore, even within the same village, there exist different forms of contract for water transaction purpose. Thus, a village level analysis may be inappropriate for an analysis of groundwater markets, but rather, we should also focus on individual-specific differences. Groundwater markets have not been analyzed either theoretically or empirically at the individual level in a systematic way within a bilateral transaction framework that takes into account of the differences in contracts. The objective of this paper is to explore the seller-buyer relationship and the determinants of water price in groundwater markets. Theoretically, I use Nash’s (1950) two-person bargaining model, and specify a reduced form groundwater price function. The bargaining model is chosen since it encompasses a commonly used model -- the principal agent model -- as its special case. I also compare pricing mechanism under different types of contracts. Empirically, I conduct regression analysis on our original data set from Madhya Pradesh in India. A notable advantage of this data set is that it allows us to match water sellers and buyers, so that I can involve both parties' individual 31 characteristics in the analysis, and with this new perspective, I can examine the claim that sellers are not necessarily exploiters. Section 3.2 provides a description of the groundwater markets in the study area with a comparison with past empirical studies; Section 3.3 lays the formal model of bilateral transaction; Section 3.4 and 3.5 present variable construction and econometric results; Section 3.6 highlights the main conclusions of this study and suggests relevant policy implications. 3.2 Structure of Water Market in the Study Area Monopoly Power One of the simple but prevalent methods of analyzing a market structure is to estimate the price-cost ratio. Researchers use the ratio to judge whether markets are monopolistic or competitive. Table 3-1 shows the summary of the past case studies and estimation results from our study area. Shah and Ballabh (1997) and Shah (1993) conclude that the water markets in areas with high ratio are not competitive but monopolistic. On the other hand, even though Fujita and Hossain (1995) obtain high value of the ratio (2.59 or 2.00), they regard the "rent" as return to seller’s capital investment in irrigation systems, given that the rate of return to capital (69 %) is close to the interest rate on the informal financial market (38 — 61 %). They conclude that if we take into consideration the risk of investment in irrigation systems, the water price is 32 economically reasonable, and “the groundwater market cannot be characterized as monopolistic, but rather it is competitive and efficient.”(pp. 456) Following the method used by Fujita and Hossain (1995), I calculate the weighted average of water-charge-cost ratio and the rate of return of irrigation investment in our study field (see chapter 2 for general characteristic of the water markets in our study field).ll While the ratios in our study area are relatively high (3.43 and 2.15), the difference between the rate of return to irrigation investment (29 %) and the interest rate of the credit program that well-owners have used for irrigation installation (12 — 15 %) is not as large as the difference in Fujita and Hossain (1995); the difference is not large enough to warrant concerns of monopolistic behavior. ’2 Thus, similar to F uj ita and Hossain’s implication, the rate of return in the study area on average does not radically exceed the interest rate at the formal credit market which the buyers would have used if they borrowed money to have their own irrigation systems. Therefore, we may have reason to doubt monopolistic water market in our study area. Individual Price Variations The absence of monopoly, however, does not necessarily imply existence of a competitive market which the past literature implies. In fact, water prices vary across ” First, I calculate the ratio of per-acre water charge to per—acre operational cost for all individual pairs of sellers and buyers, and then take average weighted on the buyer' s area of irrigation. Operational cost compose of such item as the cost of electricity, the cost of repairs and necessary parts, and wage payments to labors. Wages are paid for such works as excavating channels, operating pumps, and supervising buyer's pump-use. A shadow wage (i.e. village wage) is used for cost calculation when sellers do these works by themselves. The ratio of per-acre water charge to the sum of operational and depreciation costs is calculated in the same way. The depreciation cost of irrigation investment is estimated by the constant amount method assuming a life of 20 years of the system. The rate of retina of irrigation investment is per- acre profit over per-acre profit, where profit is per-acre water charge minus per-acre operational cost. The weighted average of each pair's rate of return is the number reported in the text. See Appendix C for detail. 33 pairs of sellers and buyers depending on specific characteristics and relationships between sellers and buyers, implying existence of bilateral transaction instead of single market in each village. Table 3-2 shows simple regression results of individual-level input prices on village dummies. If a market is competitive, we should not see large price variations at least within a village. As for seed, urea, super phosphate, and DAP, significant variations in prices are explained by the village dummies (R-squared = 0.41 for seed, 0.68 for urea, 0.70 for super phosphate, 0.73 for DAP), implying that these input prices do not significantly differ within villages. On the other hand, the regression of water price shows that there remain huge part of unexplained variations even afier removing the village-level variation (R-squared = 0.20). One potential reason is existence of only one price study area with large variation due perhaps to measurement errors. It also seems natural to conjecture that each water transaction carry a different water price which could be explained not by village-level factors as the past literature suggests, but by individual-specific characteristics of sellers and buyers. In sum, the seller may be neither monopolist nor a price-taker at a competitive market. Given this fact, now the question arises: what is the sellers' position in the water markets and whether individual characteristics of the seller and the buyer affect the water price, and if yes how do they determine the price. These issues need to be investigated empirically, but prior to the econometric analysis a formal model is presented to underpin the empirical work. ’2 Interest rates at informal credit market vary from 36 % to 60 % per year in our study area, which is usually used for the relief from short term liquidity constraint such as wedding and purchase of modem 34 3.3 The Model I assume an economy consists of two individuals: a water seller (who owns irrigation systems and provides water for production) and a water buyer (who has no irrigation systems but provides other inputs such as land and labor). There is uncertainty in production; the state of nature is represented by the random variable, 0, which is |_.r.r al.]. treated as a multiplicative factor distributed with E9 = 1 and finite variance. The payment from the buyer to the seller is assumed to be expressed by the following linear function: a0f (a, x; h,) + wa where a is a parameter representing the output share to the seller; f(.) is the buyer’s production function which depends on the amount of irrigation water (a) and the vector of inputs (x) given the buyer’s production technology and agrarian characteristics (hb), and is assumed to be a concave and linearly-homogeneous with the usual properties of positive but decreasing marginal product; w is unit water charge in case of fixed-rent or flat charge contract.13 For simplicity the seller is assumed to bear the entire cost of irrigation while the buyer takes care of other inputs. Hence, the seller’s and the buyer’s profit from water transactions are respectively defined as: agricultural inputs instead of long term investment. ' Under fixed-rent contract, w and a are set by the seller, and only w is set by the seller under flat-charge contract. There is no difference between these contracts when the contractual parameters are determined cooperatively between the seller and the buyer. 35 71's 5 a9f(a. x; hi) + W - 0(a; h.) m, E (1 —a)6f(a, x; h) — wa — pxx where c() is the irrigation cost function which depends on the amount of water (a) given irrigation technology and seller’s agrarian characteristics (hs); px is the vector of input prices; the output price is normalized to one. Following previous work on agrarian contracts, I further assume a risk-neutral water seller and a risk-averse water buyer (Stiglitz, 1974; Bell, 1989)14 Thus, the seller’s utility is measured by expected profit (E 713) and the buyer’s utility is expressed as Eu( 7a,) where u ’>0 and u ’ ’<0. Both parties do not enter into the contract unless it provides them with utility at least equal to their reservation utility. The reservation utility is formally defined as the utility that a party would get, in case of disagreement, from the best alternative usage of his resource which is currently in use. Thus, the seller’s reservation utility may be a function of the amount of water currently used by his buyer (a) and also on productivity of the alternative way of water usage which is determined by the capacity of his irrigation facility and ability of himself (hs). Likewise, the buyer’s reservation utility may be a function of the amount of resources he takes care of (x) and his ability to utilize them (hb). Due to the different attitudes toward risk, each reservation utility is written as 7r..(a,h.) 17(7—{b (x: hb)) where if, (.) is increasing with respect to a and h, for the seller, and with respect to x and h), for the buyer. '4 The data of our study field shows that the sellers are wealthier than the buyers in terms of lands, animals, and tractors, and this holds generally in Indian water markets (Saleth, 1998). Given the widely accepted idea of decreasing risk aversion in wealth, this assumption would not be unacceptable. 36 The principal-agent solution has been the most common framework for examining bilateral transactions (Salanie, 1997; Hayami and Otuska, 1993). It assumes that the principal (either the seller or the buyer) has ultimate power of bargaining, and the agent is not free to propose another contract. However, there may be the case that both parties have some power of bargaining and then the contract is formed through bilateral negotiation. We should not exclude this kind of market structure a priori when we look at newly emerging markets. Otherwise, an econometric specification would miss necessary explanatory variables and then have model specification bias in the results. Thus, we should start from a more general model. The solution concept to be employed in this paper is Nash’s (1950) solution to two-person bargaining problem.15 This solution is more general than the principal agent approach in that it covers not only the principal-agent solution as its polar case but also the case that both parties have some power of bargaining. Now define F E {E 71.01.w.a,x;h.hs)-7r.(a,h.)}5 x {E u(n1(a,w,a,x;h. hb))— 17(7r1,(x;h1,))lHS which is simply the product of the two parties’ gains from transaction, relative to their reservation utilities with weight, 6, where 0 S 6 S 1. Putting weight is the natural generalization of Nash’s program when the parties have different bargaining powers ’5 Bell and Zusman (1976) is the first paper which introduces the bargaining solution to tenancy problems. Bell (1989) shows more generalized model by adding fixed-rent contract option into the previous paper in which only sharecrop and fixed-wage are contractual options. Frisvold and Caswell (1995) apply this solution concept to water markets. 37 (Dasgupta, 1993). Assuming cooperative bargaining, Nash’s solution is the contract that yield the greatest value of 1" subject to both parties’ incentive constraints.l6 max r = {E rho-mm}; u(.>—z7(.)}“" a ,w,a,x st. Err..(-) 2 7?..(-) , E u(.) 2 i7(-) Note that when 6 = 1, the seller is assumed to possesses ultimate bargaining power and the bargaining problem becomes equivalent to the principal-agent problem in that the seller, as a principal, maximizes his profit such that the buyer, as an agent, receives at least as much as his reservation profit. The converse holds when 6 = 0. The unit water price is defined as p. E a9f(-) , w a Assuming relative strength of bargaining power, 6, is exogenously determined by both parties technologies and agrarian characteristics, namely h,, and hb, then the equilibrium- unit-water-price becomes the function of all exogenous variables, i.e. p..* = p..*(p.;h.,hs) (1) This function implies that the unit-water price may vary across the pairs of the sellers and the buyers depending on their technologies and agraian characteristics. I estimate a linear approximation of this function in the empirical section. Another distinctive implication from this model is that the unit-water price would become higher under sharecrop contract. Under sharecrop contract (0 < 01 < 1, w = 0), equation (1) is more specifically written as '6 The cooperative solution implies that there is no shirking in input provision. This may not be unacceptable assumption in the small agrarian community where people easily observe each other’s activity 38 _1_ a(.) pI.(_.,..,.,=[c(.)+2r.(.)+ 5 1 {Eu(.)-r(.)}] (2) 1—6 Eu'(.)9 where the functions on the right hand side are all at equilibrium points. This equation tells us that the seller receives the irrigation cost and his reservation profit so that he enters the contract, plus the extra profit that is transferred from the buyer depending on the relative strength of the seller’s bargaining power, (6/1-6). Under fixed-rent or flat charge contract, it becomes '7 . 5 1 _ pw(ftx/flat) = [C() + is () + SEW—(5 {Eu() - “()I] A 3 a(.) ( ) Since Eu ’0 < Eu’, the third term becomes larger under sharecrop contract.18 Intuitively the term l/Eu( )0 (or 1/Eu(.)) converts buyer’s utility to the seller’s utility (i.e. monetary term). '9 The inequality, Eu ’0 < Eu’, means that when the seller also shoulders the production risk (sharecrop contract), one unit of buyer’s utility is more appreciated in terms of money. In other words, if buyer can get the same amount of utility he is willing to pay more when the risk is shared. Thus, the difference of the third term between equations (2) and (3) may be considered as a risk premium payment from the buyer to the seller in return for the partial transfer of the production risk through sharecrop contract. Consequently, the unit water price under sharecrop contract becomes higher than under fixed-rent or flat-charge contract, given other things being equal. This implication is consistent with the principal-agent solution in the past literature (Hayami and Otsuka, (Bardhan, 1984, chapter 7). Empirical evidence is presented by Otsuka et al (1986). ’7 Under the assumption of cooperative bargaining, amount of water also becomes choice variable. Thus, there is no difference in solutions between fixed-rent and flat-charge. Actually, this is consistent with my empirical analysis which shows that there is no statistical distinction whether choosing fixed-rent or flat- charge contract (see chapter 3). 39 1993). A comparative statics with respect to p,, h,, and h), is not informative because changes of these parameters shifts both the seller’s supply schedule and the buyer’s demand schedule as well as their bargaining power. In the empirical analysis I allow the data to inform us on the signs of the effects of the different parameters. 3.4 Variable Construction The dependent variable I use is unit-water-price, which is calculated such that the ex-post total payment for water is divided by area irrigated and by the number of water applications, and then divided by wheat price to convert to wheat term.20 Researchers on water markets are concerned about qualitative difference in irrigation water. The sellers usually irrigate their own plots first and then allow the buyers to use their irrigation systems, and thus the buyers’ irrigation may be physically constrained in terms of timing and amount. As I explain later, I control for this as much as I can in my econometric analysis. Besides, I do not find notable difference in water quality in our samples, although the available information is limited.21 Turning now to the explanatory variables, for one of the seller’s characteristics, h,, I use the total investment in irrigation systems which consists of the investment of ’8 Eu'G =Eu'E9+cov(u’, 9). Since u" < 0, cov(u’, 0) < 0. Since EG =1, Eu'G =Eu'+cov(u', 0) How many water buyers?:_ (visit these water buyers’ after finishing this household.) 74 2.2.2 Operation and Maintenance Cost If you use your own labor for operation and maintenance, please fill in the days and the numbers of people. Otherwise, please enter the amount of payment in Rs. Cost Items Cost Does this cost include the expenditure for other farmers’ operation? Fuel / Electricity Bill (Rs.) a = fuel, b= 1=Yes 2=No electricity Spare Parts (Rs.) N/A Repair and Maintenance (Mechanical N/A Charge) (Rs) Well Transportation cost from house to field 1=Yes 2=No (RS) Driver’s / Linemen Salaries (Rs or days*#) 1=Yes 2=No Canal digging (Rs or days*#) 1=Yes 2=No Supervision Cost (supervision of buyers’ N/A tubewell use) (Rs or days*#) Miscellaneous (Rs) N/A 75 an :5 3: ac: >5 corn 5n onb 9% RV 3c 6038 ofi «a 28 85 as as g woo—ES 65 on 28 as E ca “was: so 956 as no 25 ea Hood 33mg %onnouo no.5 05 \850 ..\a ASE no 32 no.5 6 E 5 S 8 mm H 8x38 05 3 Bow a no: 2: no 0:?» Son. 3 ” cum BE Eon. Sancho? 28m .3358 cougar; no mooofimmooo 05 :52 on await, 05 E Boa =a 83:56 on. 652333 .8 832 swan—3 .xov oofion coo x8 .635, 2:: Bone commend ”v.08 Z A363 C movie obs no» as» 05 Home 388 cm £682 .83 Batons: ~88 05 E mnoco =w Bonn xm< N682 :03 65 .3 @6335 $o_n acetone“ “won. 2: Sons 674 :6on asaso as 835 53369.. :3 8888a 3538?. S. 76 8.3 use as .893 038 om: “one.“ 033 8: Spain 033 8: 98:2 @853 .5 6a .5 Etc 288} is» browns.» auburn 93o 53:5: mEootn when eon—SE .3 £8 05 on mots Hon—3 Snood. 2583 «ED 6: a: 9.: a: .noeo some Con Esofiw on: oEZn 8:58 20:38: 2: t 96: 9 :5: Bob 5:38 05 E Enoch :38 5 En v as 63.; Aw Aw Aw E E <25 as: can: as: as: my: use: mac 63% as: corn ba onb worn EU onb born by onb coin En onb corn in onb oEoumon oEoumon 25:32 awn—Eon uoN2E0n n20 ANAL 2-2; 2: as: 2.3 A: 3:8 63a: 77 Table: Labor Household Labor Hired Labor activitie which # of people # of days # of # of days daily month? 5 people wage“ ploughi ng manure applicati on seeding weeding harvesti n8 Which month?: In which month was the activity carried out? ‘ *If the wage is not pay per day basis, please specify the payment scheme below. 2.2.3 Water Management If you use common water sources (common well/tank or canal) for another plot, do your household members participate in water management activities? 1. Yes (what kind? and how much Rs/ day) 2. No 78 2.2.4 Dry Season without Water How large did you cultivate UNIRRIGATED area during LAST DRY SEASON (1997)?_ ha ( % of area rented IN %), Crop: Total Output: kg Price/kg: Rs (if sold) 2.2.5 Agriculture during Rainy Season How large did you cultivated LAST RAINY SEASON (1997)? ha ( % of area rented IN__%) What was the most important RAINY-SEASON CROP LAST YEAR (1997)? Area Planted: ha ( % of area rented IN %) High Yield Variety? 1=Yes 2=No Total Output: kg Price: Rs (if sold) 2.2.6 High Yield Variety When your household adopted high yield varieties, what was the most important source of information? 1. extension service 2. radio and/or TV programs 3. newspaper and/or magazines 4. neighbors 5. dealers/merchants of agricultural inputs 6. others: 79 3 Forest 3.1 Forest Use Does your household use forest for the following purposes? Timber collection 1=Yes 2=No Fuelwood collection 1=Yes 2=No Fodder collection 1=Yes 2=No Grazing 1=Yes 2=No Grass collection 1=Yes 2=No NTFP (non-timber forest products) collection 1=Yes 2=No 3.2 Forest Management Activities Does your household members participate in forest management activities funded cy PUBLIC SECTOR ? 1 = Joint Forest Management 2 = other government work 3 = none If 1 or 2, fill in the table. Activities (circle all # of people Total days of Total Revenue applicable numbers) from your working (sum as wage in kind in 1997 household of all participants) 1 2 3 4 5 6 (wage rate Rs/day) 1=Plantation, 2=Trench digging, 3=Pruning, 4=Thinning, 5=Forest watching, 6=Other Does your household members participate in forest management activities OTHER THAN the one mentioned above? 1=Yes (who organizes? ) 2=No If yes, fill in the table. 80 Activities (circle all # of people Total days of Revenue applicable numbers) from your working (sum as wage in kind in 1997 household of all participants) 1 2 3 4 5 6 (wage rate Rs/day) 1=Plantation, 2=Trench digging, 3=Pruning, 4=Thinning, 5=Forest watching, 6=Other 3.3 Fuel How often in a week does your household usually collect fuelwood? times Who and how many people usually goes to the forest to collect fuelwood? How much (kg) does your household collect fuelwood on average in one collection? kg How many hours does your household spend collecting fiJelwood in one collection? hours Does your household use cow dung for cooking? 1. Yes ( %) 2. No Does your household use kerosene for cooking? 1. Yes (___ __%) 2. No Does your household use agricultural residues for cooking? 1. Yes (— ____%) 2. No *Percentage against total energy consumption for cooking. 81 3.4 Grazing and Livestock 3.4.1 Grazing Animal current # of animals % of grazing # of animals 10 years ago % of grazing 10 years ago Oxen Cow Buffalo CS Sheep Goats Who takes care of grazing? 1=household members 2=neighbors 3=grazers (specialists) 4=other If 1=household member, Who? If 2 or 3, how much do you pay? ( __l , How many people? 82 , How many hours/day? 3.4.2. Livestock Transaction transa kind of animal numbe unit price ction r (Rs) purpose of transaction 1 2 Sales in 1997 3 Purchase in 1997 4. Credit Have you ever borrowed money from others? 1=Yes 2=No most recent If yes: When? How much? From who For what purpose? Interest? If no: Why? 1=Not needed 2=Not available 83 second recent 3=Expensive 5. Household Income Note: Ask about household income LAST YEAR (1997). Income Source Amount (RS) activity and wage rate farming (from sales of ag. products) N/A Agn culture working for other wage rate household’s plot Rs/day sales of forest products N/ A Forest working for J FM etc. wage rate Rs/day your own business activity Non-farm activities in activity the village working for other’s wage rate Rs/da y your own business activity Migration act1v1ty working for others wage rate____Rs/d ay money from non- from Remittance whom household members 84 6 Household Assets 6.1 Asset Composition Item current qty qty 10 years ago Tractor Cart Automobile Bike Bicycle TV Radio 85 7 Health and Nutrition 7.1 Nutrition How many days in a week do your household members usually take beans/pulse?_ days How many days in a week do your household members usually take vegetables?_ days How many days in a week do your household members usually take meat? days What meat is it: Does your household purchase milk? 1. Yes 2. No Does your household sell milk? 1. Yes 2. No How many days in a week do your household members take dairy products (milk, cheese, etc.) in milking season? days per week for months” per a year How many days in a week do your household members take dairy products (milk, cheese, etc.) in non-milking season? days per week for __ months" per a year *Total should be 12 months. Milking season is a period (a few months or a whole year) when one can milk cows continuously, but not necessarily every day. Non-milking season is a period when no milk is available from the household’s own animals. 86 7.2 Health 7.2.1 Drinking Water What is your household’s major drinking water sources? 1. pond, lake, or dam 2. river, or spring 3. common well, or borehole 4. common hand pump 5. private well, or borehole 6. private hand pump 7. rainwater stored in tank 8. tap water from running water (is it disinfected? 1. yes 2. no) 9. buying from water seller How ofien does your household collect drinking water in a day? times Who and how many people usually collects drinking water? people How many hours does your household spend collecting water in one collection?_ hours 87 7.2.2 Diseases In the past one year, did your household members have any diseases for which he/she had to go to health center/clinic/hospital? Please list all the cases. (1) Who (2) In (2) Name (3) Where (4) (5) Total (6) How (sex, age) which of disease did he/she Admitted expendit did you month? or go? to the ure manage to Househol symptom Type and hospital? pay the (1 head? location If yes, expense? how many days? 1 2 3 4 5 (1) If he/she is the household head, please write so. (3) Where did he/she go: answer the type of medical facility, such as health center, clinic, hospital, and place where it is located (name of the city/town). (4) Admitted to the hospital: If he/she had in-hospital care, answer “yes”. Otherwise, “no”. If yes, answer how many days he/she stayed in the hospital. (6) Self-financed or borrowed. If self-financed, then how did the household do it? (e.g. saving, selling cows, selling wheat, and so on). If borrowed, then from whom did the household borrow? (e.g. neighbors, informal money lender, formal bank, and so on). 88 FOR N ON-O WNERS The diflerence between owner ’3 question and non-owner ’s question is only section 2.2 (question on tubewell) which is shown below. The rest of the questions are the same. 2.2 Irrigation (about the plot questioned in Agriculture section) From which owner did you buy water? (specify the well if the owner has more than one: ) Did you pay for water? 1=fiee 2=charged -> How much did you pay in total to irrigate the plot questioned above? Rs (if pecuniary payment) kg of (if in kind ) If 2=charged, how did you pay? l=fixed rent per season (Rs . for ha) 2=crop sharing ( % of the total harvest) 3=mixture of 1 and 2 (Rs for ha plus % of the harvest) 4=charge per hectare per application (Rs ) 5=charge per hectare per season (Rs ) 6=charge per hour of pump-use (Rs per hour) 7=other( ) How often did you apply water to the plot you are asked above? times 89 How much did you apply water at each application? 1St application ha (or hour of pumping) 2"d application fihg (or hour 0f pumping) 3rd application ha (or hour of pumping) (more? write answer below) Operational Cost Paid by Yourself 1 =non 2=fuel (Rs ) 3=Driver’s / Linemen salaries (Rs ) or ( days by yourself) 4=transport (Rs ) or ( days by yourself) 5=chanel digging (Rs ) or ( days by yourself) 6=other (Rs ) or ( days by yourself) Did you have another plot irrigated by the same well? 1=Yes (how large? ha) Opportunity of other activities Choose the one best alternative opportunities from the following if the current well owner refused to sell water to you. (Note this is a hypothetical question to the household who actually used water last dry season.) 1=buying water from a different well owner (from whom? how far km) 90 2=buying water from other water source (type of irrigation? ha) how far km) 3=farming without water (crop? how large? 4=non-farm family business (what kind? ) 5=non-farm labor work in the village (what kind? wage rate?— Rs/day) 6=seasonal migration (what kind? wage rate?__ Rs/day) =other (what kind? wage rate? Rs/day) 91 BIBLIOGRAPHY 92 Allen, Douglas and Dean Lueck. 1992. “Contract Choice in Modern Agriculture: Cash Rent Versus Cropshare.” Journal of Law & Economics 35(2) pp. 397-426. Allen, Douglas and Dean Lueck. 1995. “Risk Preferences and the Economics of Contracts.” American Economic Review 85(2) pp. 447-451. Alston, Lee J., Samar K. Datta and Jeffrey B. Nugent. 1984. “Tenancy Choice in a Competitive Framework with Transactions Costs.” Journal of Political Economy 92(6) pp. 1121-1133. Bagachi, Kathakali S. 1995. Irrigation in India: History and Potentials of Social Management, New Delhi: Upalabdhi. Bardhan, Pranab K. 1984. Land, Labor, and Rural Poverty — Essays in Development Economics, Oxford University Press: Delhi. Basu, Kaushik. 1992. “Limited Liability and the Existence of Share Tenancy.” Journal of Development Economics 38 pp. 203-220. Bell, Clive, 1977. "Alternative Theories of Sharecropping: Some Tests Using Evidence from Northeast India." Journal of Development Studies 13 pp. 317 - 346. Bell, C. 1989. “A Comparison of Principal-Agent and Bargaining Solutions: The case of Tenancy Contracts.” In P. K. Bardhan ed., The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions, Clarendon Press pp. 73-92. Bell, C. and Minhas Zusman. 1976. “A Bargaining Approach to Cropsharing Contracts.” American Economic Review 66(4) pp578-88. Bliss, C. J., and N. H. Stern. 1982. Palanpur: The Economy of an Indian Village. New York: Clarendon Press. Campbell, Donald. 1995. “Design and Operation of Smallholder Irrigation in South Asia.” World Bank Technical Paper No. 256, Washington D. C., The World Bank. Cheung, Steven N. S. 1969. The Theory of Share Tenancy, University of Chicago Press. Datta, Samar K., Donald J. O’Hara, and Jeffiey B. Nugent. 1986. “Choice of Agricultural Tenancy in the Presence of Transaction Costs.” Land Economics 62(2) pp. 145- 158. Dasgupta, Partha. 1993. An Inquiry into Well-Being and Destitution, Oxford: Clarendon Press. 93 Dhawan, B. D. 1988. Irrigation in India ’s Agricultural Development: Productivity, Stability, Equity, New Delhi: Sage Publications Eswaran, Mukesh and Ashok Kotwal. 1985. “A Theory of Contractual Structure in Agriculture.” American Economic Review 75(3) pp. 352-367. Frisvold, George B. and Margriet F. Casswell. 1995. “A Bargaining Model for Water Transfers Including Water Quality.” In Ariel Dinar and Edna Tusakloeman (eds.) Water Quantity/Quality Management and Conflict Resolution: Institutions, Processes, and Economic Analysis, London: Praeger. Fujita, K. and F. Hossain. 1995. “Role of the Groundwater Market in Agricultural Development and Income Distribution: A Case Study in a Northwest Bangladesh Village.” Developing Economies 33(4) pp. 442-463 Hayami, Yujiro and Keijiro Otsuka. 1993. The Economics of Contract Choice: An Agrarian Perspective, Oxford: Clarendon Press. Ishikawa, Shigeru, 1975. "Peasant Families and the Agrarian Community in the Process of Economic Development." In Lloyd Reynolds (eds.), Agriculture in Development Theory, Yale University Press, pp. 451 - 496. J anakarajan, S. 1992. “Interlinked Transactions and the Market for Water in the Agrarian Economy of a Tamilnadu Village.” In Themes in Development Economics: Essays in Honor of Malcolm Adiseshiah, ed S. Subramanian, Oxford University Press. Kahnert, Friedrich and Gilbert Levine, 1994. “Groundwater Irrigation and the Rural Poor: Options for Development in the Gangeic Basin.” A World Bank Symposium. Washington D. C. Meinzen-Dick, Ruth, 1997. “Groundwater Markets in Pakistan: Participation and Productivity.” Research Report No. 105, Washington D. C., International Food Research Institute. Nash, J. R. 1950. “The Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 18, pp. 155-62. Newbery, David M. G., and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1979. “Sharecropping, Risk-sharing, and the Importance of Imperfect Information.” In J. A. Roumasset, J. M. Boussard, and 1. Singh (eds.), Risk, Uncertainty, and Agricultural Development, Ch. 17. New York: Agricultural development Council. Otsuka, Keijiro, Masao Kikuchi, and Yujiro Hayami, 1986. "Community and Market in Contract Choice: J eepney in the Philippines', " Economic Development and Cultural Change, 34(2), pp. 279 - 98. 94 Pant, N. 1991. “Ground Water Issues in Eastern India.” In Future Directions for Indian Irrigation: Research and Policy Issues, ed. R. Meinzen-Dick and M. Svendsen. Washington D. C.: International Food Policy Research Institute. Pant, N. 1992. New Trend in Indian Irrigation, New Delhi: Ashish Publishing House. Rao, C. H. Hanumantha. 1971. “Uncertainty, Entrepreneurship, and Sharecropping in India.” Journal of Political Economy 79(3) pp 578-595. Ray, Debraj. 1998. Development Economics, Princeton University Press. Robertson, A. F. 1982. “Abusa: The Structural History of an Economic Contract.” Journal of Development Studies 18(4) pp. 447-478. Rosegrant, Mark W., 1997. “Water Resources in the Twenty-First Century: Challenges and Implications for Action.” Food, Agriculture, and the Environment Discussion Paper No. 20, Washington D. C.. International Food Research Institute. Rosenzweig, Mark R. 1988. “Risk, Private Information, and the Family.” American Economic Review 78(2) pp. 245-250. Rosenzweig, Mark R. and Kenneth I. Wolpin, 1993. "Credit Market Constraints, Consumption Smoothing, and the Accumulation of Durable Production Assets in Low-Income Counties: Investments in Bullocks in India." Journal of Political Economy, 101(2), pp. 223 - 244. Roumasset, James and Marilou Uy. 1987. “Agency Costs and the Agricultural Firm.” Land Economics 63(3) pp. 290-302. Salanie, Bernard. 1997. The Economics of Contracts, The MIT Press. Saleth, R. Maria, 1998. "Water Markets in India: Economic and Institutional Aspects." In Markets for Water: Political and Performance. K. William Easter, Mark W. Rosegrant, and Ariel Dinar (eds.) Massachusetts: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Shaban, Radwan Ali, 1987. "Testing between Competing Models of Sharecropping." Journal of Political Economy 95(5) pp. 893 - 920. Shah, Tushaar, 1993. Gropund Water Markets and Irrigation Development, Bombay: Oxford University Press. Shah, Tushaar and Vishwa Ballabh. 1997 “Water Markets in North Bihar: Six Village Studies in Muzaffarpur District.” Economic and Political Weekly 27(12) pp. A183 - A190. 95 Sharma, Naresh and Jean Dreze. 1996. “Sharecropping in a North Indian Village.” Journal of Development Studies 33(1) pp. 1-39. Sengupta, Kunal. 1997. “Limited Liability, Moral Hazard and Share Tenancy.” Journal of Development Economics 52 pp. 393-407. Shetty, Sudhir. 1988. “Limited Liability, Wealth Differences and Tenancy Contracts in Agrarian Economics.” Journal of Development Economics 29 pp. 1-22. Singh, Nirvikar, 1989. “Theories of Sharecropping.” In P. K. Bardhan ed., The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions, Clarendon Press pp. 33-72. Stiglitz, Joseph E., 1974. “Incentives and Risk Sharing in Sharecropping.” The Review of Economic Studies 41(2) pp. 219-255. Stiglitz, Joseph E, 1987. “Sharecropping.” in The New Paragrave: A Dictionary of Economic Thought and Doctrine, ed. J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P Newman , MacMillan: London. vol. 3 pp. 320-23 Strauss, John and Duncan Thomas, 1998. "Health, Nutrition, and Economic Development." Journal of Economic Literature, 36 pp. 766 - 817. Tunali, Insan. 1993. “Choice of Contracts in Turkish Agriculture. ”Economic Development and Cultural Change 42(1) pp. 67-86 Walker, Thomas S. and James G. Ryan. 1990. Village and Household Economics in India 's Semi-arid Tropics. The Johns Hopkins University Press. 96