#17:... s. “I. 3. s..:.|sly 3:... 1:9! i. JL .7711.- J. . . : ’ .. V 1523... v 3... .2. pl 3 .35...» ‘ , .33... £2: “r... ..$.....§....... , 55.”. ‘ . t 0.5-- . 1.129.1«5 . .3739... V.) v. . . 1 :. H§J§hflmz flu: >4. ill .Pthturfiafifl . . . at. m“, 1:: . , I... 9...; .. ...:-m :9. r 5.; . .E. z . 53.3.; .233” . , unfi‘vaukwni :. flair... 94m“: 1L9 34% 9. 1;. 2. 5...: $13.13.. ‘ . 1.57.: 1...). .12.! 15.5... . «fivoil .! .. .3 E. 33.5. D: 5.81 .1 1.. a. gun! a .01.! .5. lllill‘g list in“. . r {I EFL ,A . .5ir1): y ffilv to v‘tbl“. SI)?- 1... C5,...” 1...! y y ‘3'.‘\ .45)-.)flivafii 3.1.: r , \- \‘l‘l‘9Q‘. . a. 14‘- » ennui... » r... 14:}. i. .12! 5“}? 1 .35.... 8: :1: .4 5.) f‘l‘ifi a THESIS 22 20:0 LIBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled The Effects of Competition and Resource on Firm Performance in Local Information Service on the Web presented by Ghee-Young Noh has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Doctoral Mass Media degree in Major professor Date May 30, 2000 MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 PLACE lN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 11100 W.“ THE EFFECTS OF COMPETITION AND RESOURCE ON FIRM PERFORMANCE IN LOCAL INFORMATION SERVICE ON THE WEB By Ghee-Young Noh A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Mass Media Ph. D. Program 2000 ABSTRACT THE EFFECTS OF COMPETITION AND RESOURCE ON FIRM PERFORMANCE IN LOCAL INFORMATION SERVICE ON THE WEB By Ghee-Young Noh The promise of a market for Web-based local information service (WLIS) has attracted nearly all forms of media including broadcasters, newspapers, and Internet ventures to a new cross-media competition and coordination. The present research is the first effort to empirically explore the mechanism of firms’ competitive advantage and performance in the WLIS. Web survey research was used to collect 183 firm data from 81 metropolitan markets. The first purpose was to assess how competition intensity affects firms’ financial commitments and performance. The competitive environment was found to strongly impact the resources available to the WLIS firm and its strategic choices. A firm’s competition intensity was also positively related to market and financial growth performance controlling for market size, income, and service age. The second purpose was to provide evidence that valuable and unique firm resources and capabilities provide the key sources of competitive advantage. Firm resources were found to be very important to the opportunity for competitive advantages. In particular, the effects of a firm’s intangible resources were stronger on firm performance and product quality than those of tangible resources controlling for competition intensity. Two competitive strategies were examined to identify the effects of firm performance and product quality. A firm’s large-scale strategy was found to have a strong impact on firm performance and product quality, while earlier entry strategy was not. The result indicates that in the WLIS industry, without effective strategies such as large-scale strategy and intangible resource commitment, first mover advantage has no effects on product quality and firm growth performance. In addition, the effects of firm’s resources were found to be stronger than the effects of market competition on firm performance. Third, the present research identified three organizational goals in the WLIS: service quality, profitability, and business competition. The goals of firms with different boundaries were found to be reflected in their allocation of resources and competitive behavior, and result in different levels of firm performance Finally, venture origin was found to be associated with a firm’s financial commitments, competitive strategies, and performance. Considering the market share and market growth performance, the current WLIS market seems to be characterized by strong competition between daily newspapers and Internet ventures. This research elaborated the link between market structure and firm performance by analyzing how market level effects are mediated by firm level conduct for firm performance and product quality. It provides empirical evidence for theoretical linkage between the financial commitment and the resource-based theory of the firm in a developing monopolistic competitive market. Copyright by Ghee-Young Noh 2000 T 0 My Mother and Father With Thanks and Love ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to acknowledge and thank the members of my committee for their support and encouragement in pursuing this area of scholarship. Dr. Thomas Baldwin, my dissertation and guidance committee chairman, was always helpful in his fiiendly and indispensable guidance and advice to complete my doctoral program. His warm encouragement and understanding provided me with a confidence needed to complete this research. Special thanks go to Dr. Stephen Lacy for his theoretical guidance and instruction. My perspective on media theory has been influenced over years by his scholarship. I had the benefit of his close and critical comments and suggestions during the entire period of my doctoral program. I am grateful to Dr. Bradley Greenberg for his special attention to detail and his efforts in keeping me learned about academic rigidity. My appreciation also goes to Dr. Carrie Heeter who first invited me into a multimedia production and offered a wonderful model of quality as both a teacher and researcher on cyberspace. Finally, I sincerely would like to thank Dr. Charles Salmon, director of the Mass Media Ph. D. program, who gave me thoughtful consideration and needed support to complete this dissertation. TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES .................................................................................. x LIST OF FIGURES .............................................................................. xvi CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION ................................................................................... 1 Purpose of the Research ................................................................... 2 CHAPTER II LITERATURE REVIEW AND HYPOTHESES ............................................... 5 WLIS Product and Market Structure .................................................... 5 Financial Commitment .................................................................... 8 Competition and Performance .......................................................... 10 Resource-based Theory of the Firm ................................................... 12 Human Resources ............................................................... 15 Organizational Coordination ................................................... 17 Innovation Resources ............................................................ 18 Market and Resources ........................................................... 19 Competitive Strategies ................................................................... 20 Scale Strategy ..................................................................... 20 Time of Entry ..................................................................... 22 Product Quality ........................................................................... 23 Organizational Goals ..................................................................... 24 Venture Origin ............................................................................ 26 CHAPTER III METHODS ......................................................................................... 29 Sampling and Data Collection .......................................................... 29 Operational Definition ................................................................... 32 Competition Intensity ............................................................ 32 Quantity of Human Resources ................................................. 33 Quality of Human Resources .................................................. 33 Organizational Coordination ................................................... 34 Innovation Resources ............................................................ 34 Market Size and Income ........................................................ 35 Product Quality .................................................................. 35 Market and Financial Growth Performance .................................. 36 Market Share Index .............................................................. 39 Organizational Goals ............................................................ 39 Service Age ....................................................................... 40 Scale Strategy ..................................................................... 40 Venture Origin ................................................................... 41 Data Cleaning for Multivariate Statistics .............................................. 41 Missing Data ..................................................................... 41 Multivariate Normality ......................................................... 42 Univariate Outliers .............................................................. 46 Statistical Analysis ....................................................................... 46 CHAPTER IV RESULTS .......................................................................................... 50 Descriptives ................................................................................ 50 Market and WLIS Profile ....................................................... 50 Product Quality and Performance ............................................. 52 Financial Commitment ................................................................... 54 Competition and Performance .......................................................... 58 Firm Resources ........................................................................... 62 Human Resources ............................................................... 62 Organizational Coordination ................................................... 75 Innovation Resources ........................................................... 77 Competitive Strategies ................................................................... 80 Scale Strategy .................................................................... 80 Time of Entry .................................................................... 83 Product Quality ........................................................................... 84 Resource and Competition ............................................................... 87 Organizational Goals ..................................................................... 89 Venture Origin ............................................................................ 97 Organizational Goals ............................................................ 97 Quantity of Human Resources ................................................. 99 Quality of Human Resources ................................................. 100 Organizational Coordination .................................................. 101 Innovation Resources .......................................................... 102 Product Quality ................................................................. 102 Market Growth Performance ................................................. 103 Financial Growth Performance ............................................... 104 Market Share .................................................................... 105 Additional Analysis: Intangible Resources .......................................... 106 CHAPTER V SUMMARY AND DISCUSSION ............................................................. 111 Financial Commitment .................................................................. 111 Competition and Performance ......................................................... 113 Firm Resources .......................................................................... 116 Human Resources .............................................................. 116 Organizational Coordination and Innovation Resources .................. 119 Competitive Strategies ................................................................. 122 Product Quality ......................................................................... 124 Resource and Competition ............................................................ 124 Organizational Goals ................................................................... 126 viii Venture Origin ........................................................................... 129 Synthetic Model and Implications for the WLIS Industry ........................ 130 Limitations and Recommendation for Future Research ........................... 137 APPENDIX A MISSING VALUE ANALYSIS ............................................................... 141 APPENDIX B MARKET CHARACTERISTICS ............................................................. 143 APPENDIX C SURVEY INVITATION E-MAIL LETTER ................................................ 145 APPENDIX D FIRST FOLLOW UP E-MAIL ................................................................. 146 APPENDD( E SECOND FOLLOW UP E-MAIL ............................................................. 147 APPENDD( F SURVEY QUESTIONNAIRE ................................................................. 148 BIBLIOGRAPHY ................................................................................ 156 ix Table 1 Table 2 Table 3 Table 4 Table 5 Table 6 Table 7 Table 8 Table 9 Table 10 Table 11 Table 11-1 Table 11-2 Table 1 1-3 Table 11-4 Table 12 Table 13 Table 14 LIST OF TABLES Descriptive Statistics ............................................................. 44 Descriptive Statistics in Organizational Goal Items ........................ 45 Profile: Service Age .............................................................. 50 Profile: Number of Employees ................................................. 51 Quality of Human Resources ................................................... 51 Change in total employment ................................................... 51 Mean of Product Quality Items ................................................ 52 Mean Importance Scores in Seven Performance Measures ................ 53 Mean Success Scores in Seven Grth Performance Measures .......... 53 Pearson Product Moment Correlations of Independent Variables for Financial Commitment Hypotheses ....................................... 54 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Human Resources (log) ......................................................... 55 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Editorial Staff (log) ............................................................... 55 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Design Stafi‘ (log) ................................................................ 56 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Technical Staff (log) ............................................................ 56 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Marketing Staff (log) ............................................................ 56 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quality of Human Resources ............................................................... 57 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Scale Strategy .......... 58 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Product Quality ....... 59 Table 15 Table 16 Table 17 Table 18 Table 19 Table 20 Table 21 Table 21-1 Table 21-2 Table 21-3 Table 21-4 Table 22 Table 23 Table 24 Table 24-1 Table 24-2 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Emphasis on Market Performance ............................................. 59 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Market Growth Performance ................................................... 60 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Financial Grth Performance ................................................ 61 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Market Share ..................................................................... 61 Pearson Product Moment Correlations of Independent Variables for Firm Resource Hypotheses ................................................. 63 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Human Resources on Product Quality .................................................................. 64 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Human Resources on Market Grth Performance ................................................... 65 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Editorial Staff on Market Grth Performance .................................................. 65 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Design Staff on Market Growth Performance ................................................... 66 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Technical Stafi‘ on Market Grth Performance ................................................... 66 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Marketing Stafi‘ on Market Growth Performance .................................................. 66 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Human Resources on Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 67 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Human resources on Market Share ..................................................................... 68 Multiple Regression of Quality of Human Resources on Product Quality .................................................................. 68 Multiple Regression of Quality of Editorial Staff on Product Quality .................................................................. 69 Multiple Regression of Quality of Design Stafl‘ on Product Quality .................................................................. 69 Table 24-3 Table 25 Table 25-1 Table 25-2 Table 25-3 Table 25-4 Table 26 Table 26-1 Table 26-2 Table 26-3 Table 26-4 Table 27 Table 28 Table 29 Table 30 Table 31 Multiple Regression of Product Quality on Quality of Technical Staff ...................................................... 70 Multiple Regression of Quality of Human Resources on Market Growth Performance ................................................... 70 Multiple Regression of Quality of Editorial Staff on Market Grth Performance ................................................... 71 Multiple Regression of Quality of Design Stafi‘ on Market Growth Performance ................................................... 71 Multiple Regression of Quality of Technical Stafi‘ on Market Growth Performance ................................................... 72 Multiple Regression of Quality of Marketing Stafi‘ on Market Grth Performance ................................................... 72 Multiple Regression of Quality of Human resources on Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 73 Multiple Regression of Quality of Editorial Staff on Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 73 Multiple Regression of Quality of Design Staff of Financial Grth Performance ................................................ 74 Multiple Regression of Quality of Technical Staff of Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 74 Multiple Regression of Quality of Marketing Staff on Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 74 Multiple Regression of Organizational Coordination on Product Quality .................................................................. 75 Multiple Regression of Organizational Coordination on Market Grth Performance ................................................... 76 Multiple Regression of Organizational Resources on Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 77 Multiple Regression of Innovation Resources on Product Quality .................................................................. 78 Multiple Regression of Innovation Resources on Market Growth Performance ................................................... 79 xii Table 32 Table 33 Table 34 Table 35 Table 36 Table 37 Table 38 Table 39 Table 40 Table 41 Table 42 Table 43 Table 44 Table 45 Table 46 Table 47 Multiple Regression of Innovation Resources on Financial Grth Performance ................................................ 79 Multiple Regression of Large-scale Strategy and Service Age on Product Quality .................................................................. 80 Multiple Regression of Large-scale Strategy and Service Age on Market Growth Performance .................................................. 81 Multiple Regression of Large-scale Strategy and Service Age on Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 82 Multiple Regression of Large-scale Strategy and Service Age on Market Share ..................................................................... 82 Multiple Regression of Product Quality on Market Grth Performance ................................................... 85 Multiple Regression of Product Quality on Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 86 Multiple Regression of Product Quality on Market Share ..................................................................... 86 Comparison of Strength of Association with Product Quality Between Four types of Resources and Competition Intensity ............. 87 Comparison of Strength of Association with Market Growth Performance Between Four types of Resources and Competition Intensity ............. 88 Comparison of the Strength of Association with Financial Growth Performance Between Four types of Resources and Competition Intensity ............................................................ 88 Factor Loadings, Percents of Variance, Reliability For Principal Factor Extraction and Oblique Rotation on Organizational Goal items .......... 91 Component Correlation Matrix ................................................ 91 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Quantity of Human Resources ................................................. 92 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Quality of Human Resources ................................................... 93 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Organizational Coordination ..................................................................... 94 Table 48 Table 49 Table 50 Table 51 Table 52 Table 53 Table 54 Table 54-1 Table 55 Table 55-1 Table 56 Table 57 Table 57-1 Table 58 Table 59 Table 59-1 Table 60 Table 60-1 Table 61 Table 61-1 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Innovation Resources ........................................................... 94 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Scale of Entry .......... 95 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Product Quality .................................................................. 96 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Market Growth Performance ................................................... 96 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Financial Growth Performance ................................................ 97 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Market Share ........... 97 Analysis of Covariance of Service Quality Goal by Venture Origin ...... 98 Mean Service Quality Goal for Five Categories of Venture Origin ....... 98 Analysis of Covariance of Profitability Goal by Venture Origin ......... 99 Mean Profitability Goal for Five Categories of Venture Origin ........... 99 Analysis of Covariance of Business Competition Goal by Venture Origin ................................................................... 99 Analysis of Covariance of Quantity of Human Resources by venture origin ................................................................... 100 Mean Quantity of Human Resources for Five Categories of Venture Origin .................................................................. 100 Analysis of Covariance of Quality of Human Resources by Venture Origin .................................................................. 101 Analysis of Covariance of Organizational Coordination by Venture Origin .................................................................. 101 Mean Organizational Coordination for Five Categories of Venture Origin ................................................................. 101 Analysis of Covariance of Innovation Resources by Venture Origin ... 102 Mean Innovation Resources for Five Categories of Venture Origin 102 Analysis of Covariance of Product Quality by Venture Origin .......... 103 Mean Product Quality by Five Categories of Venture Origin ............ 103 xiv Table 62 Analysis of Covariance of Market Growth Performance by Venture Origin .................................................................. 104 Table 62-1 Mean Market Growth Performance by Five Categories of Venture Origin .................................................................. 104 Table 63 Analysis of Covariance of Financial Growth Performance by Venture Origin .................................................................. 104 Table 63-1 Mean Financial Growth Performance for Five Categories of Venture Origin .................................................................. 105 Table 64 Analysis of Covariance of Market Share by Venture Origin ............. 105 Table 64-1 Mean Market Share for Five Categories of Venture Origin .............. 106 Table 65 Pearson Product Moment Correlations of Independent Variables for Intangible Resources Hypotheses ........................................ 107 Table 66 Multiple Regression of Tangible and Intangible Resources on Product Quality ................................................................. 108 Table 67 Multiple Regression of Tangible and Intangible Resources on Market Growth Performance ................................................. 109 Table 68 Multiple Regression of Tangible and Intangible Resources on Financial Growth Performance ............................................... 110 Figure 1 Figure 2 Figure 3 Figure 4 Figure 5 Figure 6 Figure 7 Figure 8 Figure 9 Figure 10 LIST OF FIGURES Scheme of the Research: The Efi‘ects of Competition and Resources on Firm Performance in Web-based Information Service ....... 4 Diagram of Hypotheses and Research Questions ............................ 28 Model of Competition Intensity on Relationship with Financial Commitment, Product Quality, and F irm Performance Controlling for Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age ........................ 115 Model of Human Resources on Relationship with Product Quality and Firm Performance Controlling Competition Intensity, Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age ............................................. 118 Model of Organizational Coordination and Innovation Resources on Relationship with Product Quality and Firm Performance Controlling Competition Intensity, Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age ............................................. 121 Model of Large-scale and Early Entry Strategy on Relationship with Product Quality and Firm Performance Controlling Competition Intensity, Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age ............................. 123 Model of Organizational Goal on Relationship with Firm Resources, Strategies, Product Quality, and Firm Performance Controlling Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age ....................................... 128 Model of Market Growth Performance in the Web-based Local Information Service ............................................................ 132 Model of Financial Growth Performance in the Web-based Local Information Service ............................................................ 133 Model of Product Quality in the Web-based Local Information Service ............................................................. 134 Chapter I INTRODUCTION In early 1998, 51 percent of Internet users had already accessed local applications such as news, weather, sports, real estate, and e-commerce. Moreover, 46 percent indicated that they would use sites that aggregate local content at least once a week (Krasilovsky, 1998). The promise of a market for Web-based local information service (WLIS) has attracted nearly all forms of media including television, radio broadcasters, newspapers, and Internet ventures to a new cross- media competition and coordination. There are now more than 2,900 newspapers online and more than 980 television station sites in the United States (Editor & Publisher MediaLink, March 2000). In any given local market, there can be as many as twenty local information service sites competing against one another. The marketer of local information service may have a newspaper site, an alternative weekly site, a local branch of a city guide chain such as CitySearch and Digital Cities, several TV and radio station sites, and joint ventures between media groups. Some news companies reported annual new media profits in the millions of dollars. The Web site of WCCO of Minneapolis was the first local TV site to claim profitability. Even if there have been incredible efforts to gain a competitive advantage in the industry, a model of competitive advantage and firm performance still should be established. The present research is the first effort to empirically explore the mechanism of firms’ competitive advantage and performance in the WLIS. In particular, this research focuses on local competition, firms' diverse resources, and competitive strategies to explain firm performance in Web-based local information services (WLIS). It will contribute to a firrther understanding of the WLIS market and industry, expand the limited body of studies on firm behaviors and resources in media research, and advance some important linkages between firm resources and performance to theoretical foundations. Purpose of the Research The first purpose of the present research is to identify organizational goals and objectives in WLIS. According to system theory, before the inputs are released into the systems and before the processes take place, direction in the form of goals and objectives is given to the organizational system (Connellan, 197 8). In other words, a firm should have some specific goals and objectives before the firm adopts a specific conduct. The objectives of firms with different boundaries may differ systematically, may be reflected in their competitive behavior, and could result in different levels of firm performance. Exploring the organizational goals may be the first step to picture the industry and firm behavior for the emerging business and market. The second purpose is to identify which factor is the primary cause of firms' performance in WLIS. Traditional economic research focuses on market structure such as competition as the primary cause of performance,1 while the resource-based view of the firm tends to emphasize the importance of firm-specific resources and capabilities. McGahan and Porter (1997) confirm that both market and firm effects ‘ Economists usually use the term market structure to describe how competition are important in shaping profitability. But they argue that the partitioning differs across sectors of industry. The present research examines partitioning and complementarity between firm and market effects on performance, and thereby elaborates the link between market structure and firm performance. The third purpose comes from theoretical concerns in media economics and management. The financial commitment approach is based on the competitive newspaper and local television news markets, which are characterized as oligopolies with product competition. An important theoretical issue is the applicability to media markets that contain large numbers of firms, which is characteristic of perfect competition (Lacy, 1992). This research attempts to apply the financial commitment approach to the emerging market of the WLIS. Finally, for fixture research in WLIS, this research methodologically attempts to propose and develop several measures for economic and management variables such as competition, firm resources, and performance. Figure 1 summarizes the scheme of the present research. takes place within a geographic area (Lacy, 1993). 00300800 000503 £030 00:08 “can. 0.000 3003050090 0:80 0:020 32800 0.80 09:02 5.0 ..o 05: 0.0005“. AU;— 00500005 02500800 0000:0800."— .E_u_ HH 00050001 0000500. 000052000 .000=0~_0090 08.50001 0005: 0000000000 00950001 :5“. 0.00m 000005. 00_>..0w 00000020. 00000003 0_ 00000000000 00K 00 0020000m 000 0000000000 00 flootm 00 ._. ”00000030 05 “.0 0.0055 0 2:9“. Chapter II LITERATURE REVIEW AND HYPOTHESES WLIS Product and Market Structure The industrial organizational model allows the analysis of a particular industry or market by examining the market structure. The structure-conduct- performance (SCP) paradigm posits a causal relationship wherein external market structure affects firm strategy or conduct, which in turn affects firm performance (Bain 1956, 1968; Mason, 1957). Market structure models are derived fi'om microeconomic theories such as perfect competition, monopolistic competition, oligopoly and monopoly. Given the geographic market, market structure is determined by three dimensions: the number of firms, the homogeneity of products within the market, and the extent of barriers to entry (Lacy & Simon, 1993). According to three dimensions of market structure, traditional media markets have been defined as oligopolies with product competition (Prisuta, 1979; Litman, 1988; Lacy, 1992). For example, Litman (1988) places newspaper markets between oligopolies and monopolies. An oligopoly is characterized by a market with a few firms that recognize their strategic interdependence. The growing number of media outlets in large markets, however, have made the application of oligopoly more and more questionable (Lacy, Atwater, & Qin, 1989). Recently, Chan-Olmsted (1997) proposed a multichannel media competition model by applying monopolistic competition theory at the industry level and oligopoly theory at the group level. Unlike the traditional media markets, the Web-based local information service market has a larger number of firms and lower barriers to entry even in local markets which are characteristic of perfect competition. Perfect competition markets are those with many sellers, homogeneous products, and low barriers to entry. In the perfect competition market, each firm assumes that the market price is independent of its own level of output. At higher prices, the firm sells nothing, and below the market price it faces the entire market demand curve (Varian, 1996). WLIS products, however, are not homogeneous. Each WLIS firm attempts to make consumers think that its product is different from the products of its competitors to create some degree of market power. The primary incentive for sellers to differentiate is the reduced substitutability between products. With reduced substitutability between products, price-cutting does not result in a complete loss of one's market share. Product differentiation thus gives a firm a certain power within its own market. Such a market is called a monopolistically competitive market (Chamberlin, 1962). The first step in examining the market structure is defining the market in terms of geography and product. WLIS markets are difficult to strictly define by geographic market. Chyi and Sylvie (1998) suggested electronic newspapers perform in four separate submarkets: the local information market, the long-distance information market, the local advertising market, and the long-distance advertising market. Moreover, the local information market is not limited to the resident users of the market. Long distance users can access specific local contents if they are willing to pay their attention. Another difficulty in defining the WLIS market mainly comes from its joint product nature which serves two markets with one production process. The WLIS sells information and entertainment to consumers and space to advertisers. Even the WLIS products are multiproducts that can serve markets other than the information and advertising markets (Lacy & Noh, 1997). WLISs provide electronic commerce transactions on their Web sites which may be an important revenue stream. For example, New York Times' New York Today (http://www.nytoday.com) launched a restaurant reservation service in February 2000. As Lacy and Noh (1997) argue, electronic media have ceased being just about content and allow new behaviors related to other markets. WLIS products are quasi-public goods. Even if a user consumes information or entertainment on WLIS, this action does not diminish its availability to others. The WLIS products are not used up by the act of consumption, which is called non- exhaustibility or joint of supply (Barry & Hardin, 1982). Every member also has a chance to benefit from the Web contents. In other words, it is impossible to exclude some users from consuming the Web content. Public goods are not affected by supply and demand in the same way that private goods are afi‘ected (Picard, 1989). Although most WLISs are available to all consumers, there exist some premium Web services. When users begin to pay for the WLIS in the form of subscription fees or pay-per-article, the price element begins to affect demand by losing viewers who would surf only if the price were lower. Due to these hybrid characteristics, WLISs are quasi-public goods. The WLIS products are also experience goods. Experience goods are defined as “those whose qualities and characteristics can be discovered only after the actual purchase of the good has occurred” (Ekelund & Saurman, 1988, p.63). Consumers must experience or sample them to evaluate the quality of Web content. For many experience goods, repeat purchases by consumers are commonplace. As a result, the quality of the products can be quickly discovered. In the WLIS market, consumers have a high degree of market power by repeat visiting. They can discontinue using the WLIS and move to other WLISs. The important factor, therefore, may not be the quantity of people a WLIS attracts but the quality of their experience. A WLIS that attracts just a few thousand loyal customers may ultimately be more valuable than one in which a million new people visit each month but never return (Schwartz, 1996). WLISs with loyal customers can extract higher advertising revenue from advertisers. Customer information may be valuable to advertisers and direct marketers (New York Times, October 20, 1998). The retention efforts are more important to keep customers and deter them from switching to another service. Financial Commitment Media economics uses the term market structure to describe how competition takes place. Various studies on the structure of media markets have indicated a relationship between competition and firm conduct. Litman and Bridges (1986) found that competition had an impact on the amount of money spent on the product. Competitive newspapers tended to have more wire services and larger newsholes. They called the tendency to increase financial expenditures on the news product "financial commitment." Lacy (1989, 1992) conceptualized the financial commitment theory with a set of explicit theoretical statements, which are applicable to newspaper and local TV news competition. According to the theory, as intensity of competition increases, the amount of money committed to news content increases (Lacy, 1992). Newspaper research found that competition resulted in more financial commitment on product (Kenny & Lacy, 1987; Nixon & Jones, 1956; Litman & Bridges, 1986; Lacy, 1987, 1988, 1990; Mullins, 1975; Everett & Everett, 1989). The number of wire services carried and the number of reporters per amount of news space were related positively to intensity of competition (Lacy, 1987). This is because newspapers facing intense competition must increase expenditures on the information product to attract readers (Lacy, Atwater, & Qin, 1989). Even if the financial commitment theory originated with the newspaper industry, research also confirmed the relationship between competition and financial commitment in local television news (Bustema, 1980, 1988a; Lacy, Atwater, Qin & Powers, 1988; Lacy, Atwater, & Qin, 1989; Lacy & Bernstein, 1991; Litman, 1979; Power and Lacy, 1991; Powers, 1993). For example, Litman (1979) found that an increase in competition between television networks resulted in increased programming expenditures. Bustema (1988) also found that competition in local television news was significantly related to staff size. Local news competition with another station was positively related to the number of employees in a station’s news department per daily newscast (Lacy, Atwater, & Qin, 1989). The competitive environment impacts the resources available to the venture and, as a result, its strategic choices (Chandler & Hanks 1994; Tsai, MacMillan, & Low, 1991). Even if no published studies could be found concerning the impact of competition on human resources commitment in the WLIS, traditional media research suggests a possible connection between competition intensity and human resources commitment. The rationale is that industry conditions, competition intensity, influence the opportunities available for the firm. WLIS firms facing intense competition are likely to try to difi‘erentiate their products by hiring more people and higher quality people who can do a better job. The following hypotheses attempt to extend the relationship between competition and financial commitment to the WLIS market. Moreover, in proposing a hypothesis regarding this relationship, we should point out that this relationship may be other market variable-dependent; requiring controls for market size and market income level. The efi‘ects of service age are also controlled for these hypotheses (see p.21). Hla: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to larger quantity of human resources controlling for market size, income, and service age. Hlb: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher quality of human resources controlling for market size, income, and service age. H2: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to larger scale of entry into market controlling for market size, income, and service age. Competition and Performance Sandberg and Hofer (1987) suggest that industry conditions greatly impact a firm’s performance. The competitive environment influences the market's acceptance of its products. As the intensity of competition increases in a market, the market will tend to accept the higher quality products. Previous studies support 10 the relationship between competition and content quality in the newspaper industry (Wanta, Johnson, & Williams, 1990; White & Andsager, 1990; Sylvie, 1991). In the competitive market, a firm will try to establish higher quality products for the formation and survival of a new venture. A WLIS firm faces intense competition. Therefore, it is likely to spend more money to differentiate its product which means a higher quality of product. Editorial content is the most important element to define the quality of WLIS products. Without the visual impact of shape, color, and contrast, however, WLIS content will not motivate the viewer to investigate their content. The Web design concept has two dimensions: aesthetic and functional (N oh, 1998). The aesthetic design concept refers to the extent to which Web design takes firll advantage of the artistic potential of the medium. WLIS may also contain diverse levels of functionality. Functionality refers to the quality of WLIS that is characterized by increased control over the communications process by customers. For example, ease of searching is often the most important firnctional attribute because users rarely spend enough time on any individual Web site to become expert users (Nielson, 1998) Research has supported to some degree that daily newspaper competition increases product quality in the form of more news space, more news services, and increased use of color and graphics. Kenny and Lacy (1987) found that the use of color and graphics on the front page of newspapers increased when the intensity of the competition increased. Lacy (1988) reported that increasing intensity of intercity competition among daily newspapers resulted in increases in the 11 percentage of total newsholes given to local news. Research using an index of quality in newspapers found a relationship between competition and quality (Lacy & Fico, 1989). Competition in local television news was positively related to the minutes of local news, as well as the number of minutes of all local programming (Bustema, 1988). Intensely competitive WLISs are likely to have higher quality ratings for their service products and firm performance. H3: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for market size, income, and service age. H4a: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to stronger emphasis on market performance within its business unit controlling for market size, income, and service age. H4b: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for market size, income, and service age. H4c: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for market size, income, and service age. H4d: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for market size, income, and service age. Resource-based Theory of the Firm Resource-based theory emerged from dissatisfaction with the SCP paradigm of industrial organization and neoclassical economics (Bogner, Mahoney, & Thomas, 1998). The neoclassical theory of the firm was originally designed for the theory of price determination and resource allocation. Within the industrial organization model, firms in an industry were considered to be alike in all respects 12 except for scale. There is little heterogeneity of firms in the model. As a result, the industrial organizational model emphasizes industry condition, market structure, as the primary basis for superior firm performance. The structural view has been criticized because the causal assumption ignores the dynamic influences that a firm’s strategic actions have on the industry structure (Chan-Olmsted, 1997). Penrose (1959) noted that it is inappropriate to try to reconcile the neoclassical theory of the firm with organizational theory. Neoclassical microeconomics is inadequate in dealing with dynamic growth processes based on heterogeneity of firms. As Rumelt (1974) argued, "the central concerns of business policy are the observed heterogeneity of firms and firm’s choice of product-market commitments" (p.560). They require a focus on the individual firm. The resource-based theory of the firm takes the perspective that valuable and unique firm resources and capabilities provide the key sources of sustainable competitive advantage (Barney, 1991; Conner, 1991; Hart, 1995). The resource base focuses on rents other than monopoly rents, the returns to market power. Thus the resource-based theory assumes that business strategy and performance should be viewed more as a quest for Ricardian rents (Grant, 1991). Unlike monopoly rents by market power, Ricardian rents are based on the possession of scarce and valuable resources (Barney, 1986: Peteraf, 1993). They suggest the returns to the resources from competitive advantage are over and above the real costs of the resources. The theory highlights how the deployment of unique and idiosyncratic organizational resources and capabilities can result in superior performance. Even for the new 13 venturing firm, research has shown that resources and capabilities are the source of competitive advantage (Chandler & Hanks, 1994; McGrath et. al., 1994). Sustained competitive advantage grows from firm-specific resources that cannot easily be imitated or substituted. Product strategies are dependent on resources and therefore strategy formulation starts with a resource assessment. Penrose (1959) provided a new conceptual schema for the firm as a collection of resources. Mata, Fuerst, and Barney (1995) suggested that the firm's resources be based on two characteristics: resource heterogeneity and immobility. Resource heterogeneity means that the resources and capabilities possessed by competing firms may differ; resource immobility means that these differences may be long lasting. If a firm possesses a resource that is possessed by other competing firms, that resource cannot be a source of competitive advantage. Thus common resources do not meet the resource heterogeneity requirement. On the other hand, a resource is immobile if firms without a resource face a cost disadvantage in developing, acquiring, and using that resource compared to firms that already possess and use it (Mata, Fuerst & Barney, 1995). Firms are comprised of heterogeneous bundles of resources. Six major categories of resources have been suggested: physical, financial, human, reputation, organizational, and technological resources (Barney, 1991; Conner, 1991; Peteraf, 1993, Grant, 1991). Although physical and financial resources may produce a temporary advantage for a firm, competitors or new entrants often can readily 14 acquire them on factor markets.2 Important resources in a firm must be difficult to replicate and therefore raise a "barrier to imitation" (Rumelt, 1984). Human Resources Brush and Chaganti (1998) showed that human and organizational resources are more strongly associated with certain performance outcomes than strategy in small service and retail firms. For example, technological and marketing skills significantly influence firm performance (Roberts, 1992). In particular, the most important resources are tacit or socially complex. The tacit resources are skill- based and people-intensive (Hart, 1995). Chandler (1962) highlights the importance of critical human resources: “(O)f these resources, trained personnel with manufacturing, marketing, engineering, scientific, and managerial skills often become even more valuable than warehouses, plants, offices, and other physical factors (p.383).” Even if the translation of resources into content quality is not perfect because some waste always occurs in the process (Lacy, 1992), media research has supported the relationship between resource commitment and product quality (Lacy & Fico, 1989; Lacy, Fico, & Simon, 1989). Lacy and Fico (1989) found that as human resources for a given amount of space increased, the quality of the newspaper increased. For direct performance effects, research has also suggested that staff sizes are positively related to performance in the newspaper industry (Lacy, Fico, & Simon, 1989). Power and Lacy (1991) found that size of newsroom staff was positively related to audience share for the early evening newscast. 2 . . . . . Moreover, financial resources of a larger firm are not indicative of financial resources the firm has allocated or is willing to invest in the new venture. This 15 However, the quantity of human resources is only part of human resources dimensions. Hiring more peOple does not guarantee higher quality which can do a complete job for superior performance. Sometimes, the quality of human resources has a stronger impact on firm performance than the quantity of human resources. Therefore, the effects of each dimension should be examined for product quality and firm performance. H5a: The quantity of human resources will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H5b: The quantity of human resources will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H5c: The quantity of human resources will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. HSd: The quantity of human resources will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H6a: The quality of human resources will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H6b: The quality of human resources will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H60: The quality of human resources will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. would not be disclosed. 16 Organizational Coordination Creating competitive advantage is not simply a matter of assembling a set of resources. Rents are usually earned not necessarily because of better resources, but because of better use of resources (Penrose, 1959). Resources are basic inputs into the production process. Productive activity, however, requires the cooperation and coordination of teams of resources (Chandler & Hanks, 1994). Socially complex resources depend on large numbers of people engaged in coordinated action such that few individuals have sufficient breadth of knowledge to understand the overall phenomenon (Barney, 1991; Reed & DeFillippi, 1990) Organizational coordination involves processes that redefine the firm’s product strategies, reconfigure chains of resources the firm can use, and redeploy resources through organizational structures (Sanchez, 1995). The organizational coordination builds a pattern of organizational routines within the firm. Organizational routines are regular and predictable patterns of activity which are made up of a sequence of coordinated actions by individuals. The organizational systems and routines such as relationship, planning, and structure, are central to achieving efficiencies in operations and providing superior levels of service (Brush & Chaganti, 1998). Andrews (1980) suggested that the essence of coordination is the way in which subdivided functions and interests are resynthesized. Sustainable competitive advantage involves complex patterns of coordination between people and between people and other resources (Grant, 1991). Dynamic product markets such as Web information service require frequent adjustments in 17 product strategies and coordinating the uses of product creation resources. Therefore, the following hypotheses of organizational coordination were addressed. H7a: Organizational coordination will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H7b: Organizational coordination will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H7c: Organizational coordination will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. Innovjation Resources Innovation in combining or deploying resources can lead to a competitive advantage or superior performance (Grant, 1991; Barney, 1991). Being first to market allows the firm to establish its products as the standard, which forces later entrants to follow the pioneer's rules of competition (Zahra, Nash, & Bickford, 1995). Rapid product introductions can meet customers' needs, generate profits, and preempt the competition (Zahra, 1996). In other words, they enhance the firm's ability to differentiate itself from the competition. In the early developmental stage of the WLIS, there is still much experimentation, research, and development that need to be funded by WLIS firms. For superior performance, it is essential to create a new and innovative application that others will want to copy (Outing, October 23, 1999). Companies to compete based on innovative products should be in the best position to take advantage of opportunities in rapidly changing industries such as WLIS. H8a: Innovation resources will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. 18 H8b: Innovation resources will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H8c: Innovation resources will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. Market and Resource; Market-level effects that promote homogeneity among firms coexist with firm-level effects that generate heterogeneity, just as various forms of competition coexist within the same industry (Mauri & Michaels, 1998). Thus there is a complementarity between resource-based and industrial organizations perspectives, including financial commitment theory, to explain the mechanism of firm performance. For example, Mauri and Michaels (1998) found the strong influence of industry-level drivers on R & D and advertising investment, whereas the results for performance confirmed the strong effect of firm-level drivers from the variance components methodology. Chandler and Hanks (1994) confirmed that both perceived market attractiveness and resource-based capabilities were significantly related to venture performance. Although industry effects are important, the resource-based view places primary emphasis on investigating firm-level effects on performance. Rumelt (1991) found that the variance within markets is greater than variance across markets. Roquebert, Phillips and Westfall (1996) also confirmed the dominance of firm effects on performance using variance components analysis. McGahan and Porter (1997) found that there are significant stable business segment-specific effects of 32% while industry effects on firm profitability was 19% of the total 19 variation. Even when firms follow similar strategies, the idiosyncrasy in their resources leads to different performance outcomes (Lawless, Bergh, & Wilsted, 1989) RQla: Are the effects of firm’s resources on product quality stronger than those of firm’s competition intensity? Rle: Are the effects of firm’s resources on market growth performance stronger than those of firm’s competition intensity? RQlc: Are the effects of firm’s resources on financial growth performance stronger than those of firm’s competition intensity? Competitive Strategies Scale Strategy Literature on competitive strategies for new ventures differs significantly on the domain breadth for new ventures, small- versus large-scale entry. Small scale position argued that new ventures should pursue ‘niche’ strategies concentrating on specialized products, localized business operation (Hosmer, 1957) and customized market segments, and high quality of customer services (Cohen and Lindberg, 1972). Thus they should avoid direct competition with large established firms. On the other hand, MacMillan and Day (1987) found that large-scale entry was more successful than small-scale entry. Large-scale strategies include high levels of capacity, sales promotion, service quality, advertising, and sales force expenditures. Cooper, Willard and Woo's (1986) also suggested that with the large- scale combination of resources, new ventures may develop strategies of direct competition with larger and established market leaders. 20 WLIS is defined as increasing returns business. The essence of an increasing returns business is that the product or service becomes more valuable as more customers purchase it (Hagel, 1999). The increasing returns business of WLIS mainly comes from the feature of discretionary database. Connolly and Thorn (1993) defined it as “a shared pool of data to which several participants may, if they choose, separately contribute information.” When someone contributes information to the Web, other consumers enjoy some benefit from using the information on the WLIS. WLIS include many kinds of discretionary databases such as local forum, real-chatting, diverse opinion from customers, information of local events, and even advertising. In the increasing returns business, the firm is likely to have to be aggressive to drive success in this business. It is essential to achieve a critical mass point to maximize WLIS utility, which results in product differentiation. Therefore the following hypotheses were addressed. H9a: For Web-based local information service, large-scale entry strategy will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H9b: For Web-based local information service, large-scale entry strategy will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H9c: For Web-based local information service, large-scale entry strategy will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H9d: For Web-based local information service, large-scale entry strategy will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. 21 Time of Entry By engaging in pioneering, the firm takes the competition to a new arena where its early mover status is hoped to create some basis for sustainable competitive advantage (Covin, Slevin, & Heeley, 1999). Research supported that firm age strongly impacts an organization’s resources and performance (Aldrich & Auster, 1986; Venkataraman & Low, 1994; Brush & Chaganti, 1998). Mosakowski (1993) found that firms of different ages have different combinations of human and organizational resources correlated to performance. Early entry into a young industry is also associated with higher levels of long-term performance. Many researchers have found that first entrants maintain higher market performance and higher chance of survival (Mitchell, 1991; Lambkin, 1979; Robinson & Fornell, 1985; Mascarenhas, 1997). This is because the investments made in an industry's early period create a set of strategic assets for firms that conditions their later choices (Oster, 1994). Thus, the early entrants may choose employees and agents and obtain equipment at lower market prices than later entrants. Most of all, customers may view first entrants as prototypical of the new product category (Mascarenhas, 1997). Therefore, a firm’s earlier entry into market is likely to have higher sustainable competitive advantage, which results in higher firm performance. H10a: For Web-based local information service, earlier entry into market will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and scale of entry. H10b: For Web-based local information service, earlier entry into market will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and scale of entry. 22 H10c: For Web-based local information service, earlier entry into market will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and scale of entry. H10d: For Web-based local information service, earlier entry into market will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and scale of entry. Product Quality Product quality has long been recognized and advocated as bases for competitive differentiation in growing industries. Product quality may be described as the characteristics of a product or service that can contribute to the fulfillment of stated or implied customer needs and wants (Garvin, 1984, Reeves & Bednar, 1994). The level of product quality reflects product differentiation. Product differentiation has two dimensions: horizontal and vertical (Whinston, Stahl, & Choi, 1997). Products are considered to be differentiated horizontally if the difference is based on appearance or consumer preference. When all consumers prefer a product among equally priced products, the products are considered to be vertically differentiated. Thus products are differentiated vertically if their qualities are different. Cost-reducing mass production technology is no longer a major concern for digital products. If products are differentiated, each seller has some degree of market power over those consumers who prefer their product. Customization is an extreme example of product differentiation in which products are produced to match the specific demand of a small group of consumers or even one individual (Whinston, Stahl, & Choi, 1997). Empirical evidence is supportive of the proposition that product quality should enhance market performance in media industry. For example, the level of 23 newspaper quality was positively related to circulation (Lacy & Fico, 1989). Lacy and Sohn (1990) found that as inches of copy devoted to stories about the suburbs increased, metro daily penetration increased. Customers tend to be drawn to quality outputs and form loyalties toward the providers (Kroll, Wright, & Heiens, 1999). A WLIS competing for the same customers must match the quality of the competing WLIS in most areas and differentiate themselves in other areas for higher level of firm performance. H1 1a: For Web-based local information service, product quality will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H1 lb: For Web-based local information service, product quality will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. H1 1c: For Web-based local information service, product quality will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. Organizational Goals The firm's goal in traditional microeconomic theory is assumed as profit maximization. Criticizing the simplicity of the firm's assumed goals, other alternative theories regarding the goals of firms suggests goals other than profit maximization. Baumol (1967) has suggested that firms work to maximize sales revenue. Marris (1964) argued that the goals of the firm are to maximize shareholder's capitalization. All goals in the end may relate to maximize profit or shareholder's value but the firm has a number of subgoals. The firm cannot be sure of the relative contribution of any single subgoal to the profit or shareholder's value. Some of the 24 multiple goals involved in performance evaluation will be compatible, but others may come into conflict. When multiple goals exit, how do we determine which one is influencing strategic behavior? This may depend in part on the structure of the set of goals. Research suggests that the structure of goals is hierarchical in nature (Beach 1985; Maslow 1970). However, the organization of goals has a more fluid arrangement. One goal can sometimes be more or less important than alternatives. For example, profitability may not be an important goal in the initial stage of a new venture. Regardless of the structure, research on the organization of goals suggests that separate but compatible goals be grouped into relatively homogeneous categories of goals (Murphy & Cleveland, 1995). Demers (1996) reported three homogeneous categories from newspaper management: product quality, profit, and community involvement. Rhea (1970) also conducted research on the goals of broadcast news directors. He included 11 task-oriented goals including profit, product quality, community involvement, licensing, and market position. Bates (1997) found that the primary focus of local television sites remains promotional, with a secondary emphasis on providing information content. Some WLIS firms are competing for the future. The firms should be concerned not only with the present profitability, but also with its fixture positions and source of competitive advantage (Hamel & Prahalad, 1994). With firms that have different sets of goals, the impact of management pursuing the goals can vary. The goals of firms with different boundaries may differ systematically, may be reflected in their allocation of resources and competitive behavior, and could result in different levels of firm performance. The 25 following research questions attempt to identify organizational goals and the effects of the goals on resource allocation and competitive strategies in WLIS. RQ2a: What kinds of organizational goals are most likely to be sought through local Web-based local information service? RQ2b: How do firm's organizational goals affect firm resources such as i) quantity of human resources, ii) quality of human resources, iii) organizational coordination, and iv) innovation resources? RQ2c: How do firm's organizational goals affect large-scale entry to compete with other firms? RQ2d: How do firm's organizational goals affect i) product quality, ii) market growth performance, iii) market share, and iv) financial growth performance? Venture Origin Five venture origins are found in Web-based local information service. The market of WLIS may have daily, weekly newspaper sites, TV station sites, radio station sites, and Internet ventures. The Internet venture is defined as a local branch of a city guide chain such as CitySearch or Digital Cities, independent city guide, and joint venture between media groups. Newspapers have a big advantage in being able to easily port over news content composed for print directly to a Web site. TV stations have their most valuable content in video form, which when ported to the Web presents serious bandwidth problems. One successful business model is the 'cluster' strategy where several weekly newspapers are grouped together on one site. By clustering groups of weekly newspapers onto shared regional sites, the content is updated more frequently—either every day or every few days. This schedule means that the Web 26 site gets fresh news almost every day from at least one of the cluster weeklies on the site (Sullivan, 1998). Oster (1994) defined a strategic alliance broadly to include any arrangement in which two or more firms combine resources outside of the market in order to accomplish a particular task or set of tasks. In a joint venture, a separate entity is set up and the contributing firms each transfer resources to the partnership and receive ownership rights over the common property. Strategic alliances have been particularly common in the WLIS industry. For example, TV-newspaper joint ventures can combine newspaper reporting with video from the TV station ported to the Web. Research suggests that venture origin is an important source of resource differences, and a source of differences in strategies and performance (Knight, 1989; Miller & Camp, 1985; Shrader & Simon, 1997). The origins may be a powerful variable in explaining the differences of resources as well as firm performance. Figure 2 displays a diagram of hypotheses and research questions for the present research. RQ3a: How does variation in venture origin affect firm's organizational goals? RQ3b: How does variation in venture origin affect firm's i) quantity of human resources, ii) quality of human resources, iii) organizational coordination, and iv) innovation resources? RQ3c: How does variation in venture origin affect firm’s i) product quality, ii) market growth performance, iii) financial growth performance, and iv) market share? 27 .0m0m0262 20.003 0.300) 00E000. 0.001 000000302 3.00 >._. .000. 50:0 eaco> 0:0 .000. 2.80 050000090 200w 000.005. 530.0 0000.2 530.0 .0.0000_n. W000scoton. 00E 2.... VI 0 .00000000. 000500.... + + 90w 0.000-093 0... ............................. km E... 50m. 00.0mm. 0.8.50. 8.... 00050001 0000500. E... 0000060000 0000000090 6.... 00050001 0000:... 00 3.0.5 GI. 00050001 0005... 00. £00030 0 . 00.000. 000 05w 00000.2 00000030 0200001 000 0000500>100 E0505 N 0.50.". 28 Chapter III METHODS Sampling and Data Collection The first step was to identify markets for Web-based local information service (WLIS). The t0p 100 metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) were chosen from the Editor & Publisher Market 1999 Guide. To create a master list of WLISs in the top 100 MSAs, media Web search engines were used, the E & P Online Media Links’, Ultimate TV‘, and Yahoo5 search engines. Even though the E & P Online Media search engine includes comprehensive URL information across all types of media, it is specialized in newspapers and city guides. The E & P Online Media Links were used to generate the URLs of daily, weekly newspapers and city guides. Television station URLs were collected from the Ultimate TV search engine and radio station URLs from the Yahoo search engine. Three search engines allow for a search of an individual WLIS’s URL based on completing the search fields: name, city, county, or state. Each search engine was used as a complementary frame to obtain a complete list of WLIS population in the top 100 MSA markets. The master list included daily newspapers, weekly newspapers, local television stations, city-guides, and radio station sites, which provide local applications such as local news, classifieds, local entertainment, weather, and local forums. The list incorporated 271 TV stations, 326 3 URL: http://emedial .mediainfo.com/emedia/ ‘ URL: http://www.ultimatetv.com/tv/us/ 5 URL: http://dir.yahoo.com/News_and_Media/Radio/By_Region/U_S__States/ 29 radio stations‘, 296 newspapers, and 84 Internet venture, totaled 977 WLISs in the top 100 MSA markets.7 The highest-ranking managers in WLIS (e. g. general manager, new media director, online editor) were selected as respondents to the survey for the firm data. The e-mail addresses of the managers were collected by searching contact information on their Web sites. If a personalized e-mail address of the manager was not found on the Web site, a representative e-mail address was chosen. A small-scale pilot study was conducted to test the survey instrument and implementation. Twenty five sites from smaller markets were selected for the pilot study. It was conducted the same as the main study procedure. A review and evaluation of the pilot study suggested a few minor changes in wording for the final survey questionnaire and invitation e-mail letter. The self-report questionnaire was administered to the highest-ranking manager sample using Web format during January and February in 2000. A four-wave data collection procedure for the Web format survey was employed. Each wave procedure had an interval of two weeks. The first step in data collection was sending e-mail "Response Invitation" letters, which described the study and invited respondents to participate in the survey on the Web. This included a hyperlink to the survey questionnaire in the body of the e-mail message. The response invitation allowed 6 Many local radio Web sites are operated by the same Web site management team under one general manager in a local market. In the case of multiple ownership in a local market, just one site was selected for a master list of WLIS. 7 The total number was extended after a pilot study that revealed a lower response rate (about 20%) than the researcher expected, to achieve the required case size for this study. 30 people to either click through to the survey or enter the URL in their web browser because URL links are not supported by all e-mail software packages. Those individuals not responding after two weeks were sent a reminder e-mail message with a hyperlink to the survey questionnaire. The people not responding after the first and second step were sent a third reminder message. For the fourth wave, those individuals not responding even after the third wave were sent the original response invitation letter. The response invitation letters were distributed to 977 WLIS site managers in the top 100 MSA markets by e-mail. The Web survey questionnaire was located at Michigan State University Web server (http://www.msu.edu/~nohgheey/issurvey.htm). Of the 977, 93 8 were returned not deliverable with reasons of unknown destination address, permanent connection timeout, and quota exceeding. Of the remaining 884 managers, 110 submitted their responses on the Web at first wave, 45 at second wave, 20 at third wave, and 12 at fourth wave for a response rate of 21 .2 %.9 Four invalid responses were excluded in statistical analysis. For the multiple correlation testing, required case size depends on a number of issues, including the desired power, alpha level, number of predictors, and expected effect size. According to rules of thumb (Tabachnick & Fidell, 1996), more than 162 cases are needed for this research with a 8 For 121 undelivered e-mails through the third wave, the e-mail addresses were rechecked on the Web sites. The e-mail address of the next highest-ranking manager in the same firm was collected if it was available. Thirty one new addresses were found and incorporated in the fourth wave. Of the 31, three were returned not deliverable. 9 The response rates by venture origin were 17.3 % of TV stations, 15.0% of radio stations, 22.3% of newspapers, and 25% of Internet ventures indicating a good reprentation of each venture type. 31 total of 14 independent variables to test multiple regression. '0 With 183 valid respondents, the number of cases is well above the minimum requirement for testing overall correlation and individual predictors. Market data for 81 MSAs were collected from the E & P Market 1999 Guide. Operational definition Each of the relevant constructs for the present research was measured by multiple-item scales. Because several original scales vital to this research are introduced, no previous reliability estimates exist. Therefore coefficient alphas were calculated as an indicator of internal consistency on the scales. All composite scales were above the minimum reliability level of .65.11 Competition InterLity Competition intensity was measured by asking the following question about five statements: “At your Web site, how much concern do you have for competition from other local Web sites?” A seven-point scale, with a range fi'om "strongly disagree" to "strongly agree", was used. One statement of “Our site overall is very different from others in the Web service” was found not to contribute to the scale and reacted in reverse direction of what had been anticipated. As the statement was dropped out, the competition intensity scale demonstrated a higher internal reliability. The scale of competition intensity was reduced to four statements. The coefficient Cronbach alpha for the scale was .74. The overall mean of competition intensity 1° For testing individual predictors, only 118 cases are needed. '1 No standard rules exist for evaluating the magnitude of reliability coefiicients. However, Nunnally (1978)’s guideline suggests that in the early stages of research, modest reliability in the .50 to .60 is acceptable. 32 scale was 19.295.12 At your Web site, how much concern do you have for competition from other local Web sites? Please select the number that best describes your approach. Strongly Strongly Disagree Agree Our budget Is increased as competition develops. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 ‘ Eliminated from the scale. Quantity of Human Resources The quantity of human resources was operationalized by indexing the number of full-time equivalent employees in four task areas: editorial, design, technical and marketing. The quantity was measured by asking the question: "In the following areas, how many full-time equivalent do you have for your Web site?" Respondents were asked to consider two half time staffs as one full-time staff for the total number of employees. Qu_ality of Human Resources Respondents were also asked to rate their employees for overall quality with the following question: "Compared to your top market competitor in your city market, how do you evaluate the quality of your employees working on the following areas?" A seven-point response scale was used with a range from "much worse" to "much better." The standardized item alpha for the quality of human resources scale ’2 Group means by venture origin were Internet venture 20.95, daily newspaper 20.91, television station 19.42, weekly newspaper 19.16, and radio 17.11. The fact that there is variability across the five categories, suggests validity of the competition intensity measure. 33 was .72. Compared to the top competitor in your city market, how do you evaluate the quality of your employees working on the following areas? Please select the number that best describes your Web business unit. Much Worse Much Better ...E4119r1.9'_§1aff .................................... 1 ..................... .2 .................... 3. ................... 4 .................. 5.. ................................. 6 ........................................ Z ..................... ................................................................ I 2 a 4 5 5‘ .. 7 .. - ................................................................. 1 2 3456 7 .. ’ """"""""""""""""""""""""""""""" I """"""""" 5 """""""""""" a?7T7iff'j;.Egléééiii?:iz;§;fli’ffifffiféjffifffiff'ii'faffijf’.Tiff 17.)) Organizationg Coordination The level of organizational coordination was measured by the following four items. Respondents were asked to respond to “To the best of your knowledge, how do you evaluate your organizational routines in the following areas?” Response scale was seven-point scale with a range from “very poor” to “excellent”. The standardized item alpha for the scale was .76. To the best of your knowledge, how do you evaluate your organizational routines in the following areas? Very Poor Excellent Coordination between editorial staff and 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Innovation Resources The level of innovation resources was measured by six statements. Respondents were asked to respond to “The following statements deal with specific resources that a business unit may have. To the best of your knowledge, please check 34 the number that represents how much you agree with the following statements.” A seven-point response scale was used with a range from "strongly disagree" to "strongly agree". The standardized item alpha for the scale of innovation resources was .84. The following statements deal with specific resources that a business unit may have. To the best of your knowledge, please select the number that represents how much you agree with the following statements. Our business unit: Strongly Strongly Disalee Agree Is very eager to try fresh ideas. _ , 7 1 2 3 4 . 5 6 . 7 Is respected by our Industry for successful use of 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 anew Ideas , ,_ Market Size and Income Market size was measured by the number of Internet users. Respondents were asked to provide the estimated percentage of Internet users in their metropolitan market. Then the estimated percentage was multiplied by the population of the MSA market. Because more than one person responded from each market, some variation in responses to the estimates of Internet user penetration was found. In that case, the mean estimates of the responses at the same market were used. Gross income per household was used for market income level. Product Quality Respondents rated their product quality compared with the top competitor in their local market on a seven-point response scale ("much worse" to "much better") for three aspects of product quality: editorial, aesthetic, and fimctional quality. The 35 editorial quality was measured by the following four items: depth of the information, original content, immediacy of the information, and breadth of the information (or = .85). Four items were used for the aesthetic quality measure: visual effects, aesthetic design, vividness of images, and layout (or = .92). The functional quality was measured by the following four items: easy of use, degree of customization, security of transaction, and bulletin board fisnction (or = .69). Overall product quality was operationalized and measured by the sum of the three subscales of product quality including 12 items (or = .87). Compared to the top competitor in your city market, how would you rate your service quality in the following areas? Much Depth of the information Market and Financial Growth Performfliaa Respondents were asked to rank their firm performance on four market and three financial growth performance measures for the previous twelve-month period. In principle, more objective measures would be preferred. However, the objective data are not available to the public and no standard measure has been established for 36 firm performance in the Web-based information service. Moreover, past studies of business policy and strategy have shown that self-reported ratings by knowledgeable respondents provide valid measures of firm performance (Conant, Mokwa, & Varadarajan, 1990; Dess & Robinson, 1984; Robinson & Prearce, 1988; Venkatramna & Ramnujam, 1987). There is no commonly accepted measure for performance, especially in new ventures. The use of profitability measures such as return of equity to evaluate new venture may be questioned, because it is affected by owner's salaries and other cost items that are frequently not disclosed by the venture (Zahra, 1996). Strong profitability may or may not be an important objective for a new venture (McDougall & Oviatt, 1996). For example, the development of a new product and brand identification may be a more important performance criterion than profitability in the initial stage of venture's progress. The multiple measures were used to reflect the multidimensionality of the performance construct (Priem, Rasheed, & Kotulic, 1995) focusing on firm’s growth. The seven-item performance scale gauged managers' perceptions of their venture's performance. Two evaluations per performance item were used. The first indicates the importance of each performance measure in their firm. Respondents rated the importance of performance measures in their business unit on a seven-point response scale (1= not at all important to 7 = extremely important). The second indicates the extent managers evaluated their firm’s success in the seven performance measures. Respondents were asked to rate their performance success during the last 12 months on a seven-point scale (1= not at all successful to 7: extremely successful). 37 Importance scores were multiplied by their corresponding performance success scores. Each multiplied score was summated for multiple performance measure. The market growth performance was measured by the following four items: advertising sales growth, e-commerce sales growth, brand identification, and market share. The standardized item alpha for the market growth performance scale was .76. The financial growth performance was measured by the following three items: return on investment, return on equity, and net profit margin. The standardized item alpha for the financial growth performance scale was .97. How much importance does the top management at your organization place on the following performance areas? Not at all Extremely important important Advertising sales growth . 1 2 ‘_ 3 4 5 6 7 f Net profit margin 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 How successful was your Web service in the following performance areas during the last 12 months? Not at all Extremely Increasing successful successful Net Jrofit margL 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 38 Mt Share Index In addition, respondents were asked to provide the average number of visitors a day on their Web site. For market share index, the average number of visitors was divided by the market size defined as the number of Internet user in a specific market. Organizational Goals The organizational goals were measured by the following 22 statements which comprise of measures for newspaper organizational goals suggested by Demers (1996), for local television station suggested by Rhee (1971) and original measures. ‘3 The following statements represent organizational goals that a business unit may pursue. Please indicate how much importance top management at your Web-based service places on the following beliefs or values by selecting the number that best represents the importance. Not At All Extremely Important Important .5 N (A) #1 0| Q N .................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................. 4 g” I '3 This study uses the informant approach to measure organizational goals which asks employees to define the goals or rank-order them (Demers, 1996). 39 The adopted measures were partly reworded for the present study. Respondents were given a series of statements and asked to indicate the extent to which they agree with each statement on 7-point scales ranging from "not very important" to "extremely important." Due to the use of the adaptive and original measures, a confirmatory stage was necessary to establish the reliability of components in the individual scales (See statistical analysis and results chapter). Service Age Service age was measured by asking the following question: "At what date was your Web site first operational as service (after any trial periods)? The Editor & Publisher MediaLink database also provides the starting date of television station and newspaper sites. The information from the MediaLink was used for incomplete responses. Scale Strategy Respondents were asked to evaluate the following scale strategy items adapted from McDougall and Robinson (1990). Respondents were given a series of statements, which represent the methods by which business may compete and asked to indicate the extent to which they agree with the following statements on a seven-point scale ranging from "never emphasized" to "always emphasized." Two items, “ Serving limited or specific geographic markets” and “Providing a narrow range of services,” were evaluated to have a weak empirical and construct validity, even though they were recoded in a reverse direction during the analysis phase. The two items were deleted from the index and the index reduced to four items. 40 Each of the following items represents different methods by which businesses may compete. Please select the number that best describes the emphasis your business unit has placed on the means of competition. Never Always emphasized emphasized .................... 123 4567 "1:.ij"ffi'j'f'f'ff'j7Tf.i'i'f'i'i'fi'i'f'j'f"77ff"'f'i'fi7"”"'.’f‘f'if'i‘fi”.'.j'i'fj’fi'fi'f'f'j'ffj'j'j'ff'fif71".ff'f'if’jf7ff'j'i‘ff'f'flff'iI'Tif'ff{231?fffff5'ifffEEEiiIiQi? f'ii$355???iffifIffIffléf'f'f'f'f'fji777Tf‘ff'ff .................................................................................................................................................................... 123 4 5 6., 7... :iiéézerovrmng high level of . . W'Provrdrng a narrow range of services 'Eliminated from the index Venture Oragia Venture origin was coded by the classification of the E & P's MediaLink directory (1: TV station, 2: Daily Newspaper, 3: Radio station, 4: Internet Venture, 5: Weekly Newspaper). Internet venture includes city guides and joint ventures between media groups. The venture origin of WLIS was also checked by visiting the Web sites. Data cleaning for Multivariate Statistics Prior to statistical analysis, all items and scales were examined through various SPSS programs for accuracy of data entry, missing values, fit between their distributions, and the assumptions for multivariate analysis. Missing Data Reviewing and examining the pattern of missing data suggested that missing values scattered randomly through the data matrix. All variables on the data matrix had missing values on less than five percent of the cases except ‘User’ variable which 41 is used for “Market Share.” Regression method was used to estimate missing values, except the “User” variable. For the estimation, other variables were used as independent variables to write a regression equation for the variable with missing data serving as dependent variable. Then the missing values were replaced by the regression estimates for the cases. For ‘User’ variable, however, there are 30 cases with missing values--more than 5% of the cases. Since the variable is used for a dependent variable and considered to be critical to the hypotheses, the 30 cases that failed to provide scores were just deleted instead of replacing the missing data for statistical analysis. The results of missing value analysis are displayed in Appendix 1. Multivariate Normality Multivariate normality is the assumption that each variable and all linear combinations of the variables are normally distributed. The multivariate normality of variables was assessed by both statistical and graphical methods. After screening continuous variables for multivariate normality, four variables were found to have substantial positive skewness with nonnormal kurtosis: “Market Size,” “Income,” “Market Share,” and “Quantity of Human Resources.” With nonnormality of the variables, a logarithmic transformation was applied to four variables. For the “Market Size” variable, skewness was reduced from 2.063 to .368 and kurtosis reduced from 4.326 to -.527 by the logarithmic transformation. For the ‘Income’ variable, skewness was reduced from .995 to .515 and kurtosis reduced from 1.627 to .502 by the logarithmic transformation. For the ‘Market Share’ variable, skewness was reduced from 2.856 to -.332 and kurtosis reduced from 9.144 to -.475 after data 42 transformation. For the ‘Quantity of Human Resources’ variable, skewness was reduced from 2.395 to .285 and kurtosis reduced from 7.377 to -.501. Table 1 displays descriptive statistics of continuous variables used for the present study. On the other hand, 22 items of the ‘Organizational Goal’ were checked for multivariate normality before factoring the items.14 The distribution of all the variables showed substantial negative skewness. A reflected logarithmic transformation was applied to the organizational goal items to improve their normality. Thus the items with negative skewness were converted to those with positive skewness prior to logarithmic transformation. Skewness and kurtosis were substantially reduced after the transformation of data. Table 2 shows descriptive statistics for organizational goal items. " As long as factor analysis is used descriptively to summarize the relationship in a large set of observed variables, assumptions regarding the distributions of variables are not in force. However, even when the statistics are used purely descriptively, normality of variables enhances the analysis (Tabachinick & Fidel, 1996). 43 0.00. 30..- 00.. 000. 000.00 0000.00 8.0.: 8.0 00. 8000:0000 5320 .0055“. 0.00. 000.- 000. 08.- 02.00 0000.02 8.02 00.0 00. 0000000000 5320 0000.2 000. 0:..- 09. 000.- 000.. 88. 00.0 00.0. 00. .02. 22.0 09:02 0.00. 000.- 000. 30.- 000.0. 200.00 8.00 8.00 00. 0.00:0 .8020 0.00. 000.- 00.. 000.- 000.0 0000.0. 8.00 8.0 00. 062000 2000-00.0.. 000. 000.- 00.. 000.- :00 88. 8.0 00.0- 00. 08582 0_0_0=0§ 0.00. 0.3.- 00.. 000.- 000.0 003.00 00.00 8.00 00. 08582 8000,25 0.00. 0.0.0.. 00.. 03.- 000.0 33.: 8. .0 8.0 000 8005038 080000090 000. 00. 000. 000..- 000.0 3.00.0. 8. 00 8.0 00. 085002 5&2. 00 000:0 0.00. 30.. 000 000. 000. 000.. 0: 8. 00. .000 009382 000.2. 00 0050.0 000. 30. .- 000 000- 0.0. 3.00 :- 0 00. 090 02200 0.00. 000. 00.. 0:.- 0000 0.00.2 8.00 8.0 00. 0.000.... 80080.00 0.00. 000. 00.. 000. 08. 0005 00.0. 00.0 00. as. 058:. 0.00. 0.00.- 000. 000. .00. 200.0 00.0 00.0 00. as. 00.0 0000.2 .00 0.0203. .00 0005000 0.0 000.2 522 5.2 2 _. 0.00... 00.00006 020000000 smn. 5N. ..- on w. co 0. EN. vvoN. mm. 8. ”up NNI404 smn. man... on 0. 8o. QNN. flour. as. 8. n3 ..Nl404 smo. com. 0.. on 0. mac. 9.3. «can. mo. 8. n2. ch404 smn. moo.- cw 0. won. mam. 5 ..N. vs. cc. an. a _.I404 smn. Na 0..- cw 0. con: NmN. Gown. no. 8. mm.- » Pl404 smn. mum: on ... moo. s 0N. ova ... cs. 8. «3 s wl404 smn. waNr on P. oNa. n ..N. mvo 0. us. 8. 03 o 0I404 smn. wNNr co 0. n 5.0 sow. omvw. vs. 8. me n wl404 smn. smn. ..- an F. own. NsN. osz. mm. 8. now v—.I404 smn. wow. F.- oo 0. sac. 3N. omen. mm. 8. now a Fl404 smn. one. ..- on ... wsn. mNN. noNN. as. 8. n3 N 0..-404 smn. 3m. 0.. cm 0. o 3. va. Noam. mo. co. n3. :I404 smn. 3°. ..- on ... ovv. 0mm. wNmN. mm. 8. now 0 wl404 smm. 8n. ..- on _.. mm 0. wsN. 63». mm. 8. now al404 smn. sw F. ..- on ... 3v. ONN. coow. cs. 8. 03 ”I404 smn. o8. P. co ... mom. saw. Nun 0. as. oo- now sl404 smm. on ... F- on ... smmr msN. mN 0v. mm. co. m2 ol404 smn. v~w.- an 0. com . _. ..N. N05 0. vs. cc. «2. ml404 smm. mm P. ..- oo 0. 3N. mvN. N 5N. mo. 8. n9. vl404 smn. soar on ... nmm. ..NN. :ow. vs. cc. n8 ”I404 smm. smo. F- co ... ”mm. s N. 50 ... Ns. co. m2 Nl404 smm. mom; on F. 9.3. scN. ova F. «s. cc. no. _. 404 .00 £02.03. dd mmoEsmxw 0.0 0002 082 £2 2 0E0: .000 _mco_.m~_cmo._0 E 0000005 0305000 N 03m... 45 Univariate Outliers Searching for univariate outliers was performed by Missing Value Analysis and Explore Analysis (See Appendix 1). The influence of univariate outliers was reduced by assigning a raw score on the offending variable that is one unit lager or smaller than the next most extreme score in the distribution as Tabachicnick and Fidell (1996) suggested. The search of multivariate outliers was performed by computation of Mahalanobis distance for each case on regression procedure. Mahalanobis distance is the distance of a case from the centroid of the remaining cases where the centroid is the point created by the means of all the variables (Tabchnick & Fidell, 1996). Because Mahalanobis distance is distributed as a chi square variable with degree of freedom equal to the number of independent variables, multivariate outliers were determined by the value of x 2 at the .001 alpha level. Statistical Analysis Standard multiple regression was performed to test hypotheses and assess relationships among variables for research questions. Multiple regression is used to control possible confounding variables that may influence the hypothesized relationship between variables. The WLISs which responded are not a random sample even though the survey attempted a census of the top 100 MSAs. Therefore, tests of substantive significance were used to interpret the regression analysis and test the hypotheses. Even though statistical significance was reported in each result table, it was not used for purpose of hypothesis testing and inference because inferential statistics assume random sampling 46 with a perfect response rate (Babbie, 1992). The test for hypothesis support was set at a semipartial correlation of .20 or higher.15 Semipartial correlation expresses the unique contribution of the independent variable to the total variance of the dependent variable. On the standard multiple regression, the value of semipartial correlation, when squared, indicates the amount by which R would be reduced if an independent variable were omitted from the regression equation. This criterion of the .20 semipartial correlation indicates that 4% of the variance in the dependent variable is exclusively shared with an independent variable. For research question 1, squared semipartial correlations on each regression were used to determine the degree of association. As two values of squared semipartial correlation showed a difference of more than .02 (2%), the degree of association for each variable was interpreted to be different. For research question 2, a principal components factor analysis was performed to reduce a large number of organizational goal items and identify main organizational goals because none of the variables was designed as dependent, and no grouping of observations was assumed (Rencher, 1995). The principal components analysis uses units (1.00) in the principal diagonal of the correlation matrix. Oblique rotation was judged to be more reasonable than orthogonal rotation because it seems more likely that factors generated from organizational goal items are correlated than they are not. The factor correlation matrix showed that two component correlations exceed .32, indicating there is enough variance to warrant oblique rotations. 1’ A higher standard would increase the chance of type II error, which should be avoided at this stage of research because this is an under-researched topic (See Shaver 47 Before factoring organizational goal items, screening mean scores of the items was performed to find inappropriate items for the organizational goal. One item “Supporting local community leaders” was found to be inappropriate because the mean score of the item was less than 4.0, a center point of response scale. In other words, the item was least used for organizational goal. Then each factor was obtained using oblique rotation with a cut-off eigenvalue of 1.0. The criterion for a variable to remain in the factor analysis was a loading of at least .50 (Comrey & Lee, 1992) A factor with less than 2 items was removed to produce reliable scales. A principal components analysis of the 21 items resulted in four eigenvalues greater than 1.00. Four-factor solution contained a factor with just two items. The two items were removed for next step factoring. On the three-factor solution, one item “Keeping the service growing and expanding” was loaded less than .50. Another item “Being the best” was multi-loaded more than .40. Therefore two items were deleted for the final solution. The present study reports the results of the oblique rotated three-factor solution with 17 organizational goal items. To assess the internal consistency of multiple-item measures, the Cronbach coefficient alpha was estimated. The standardized item alphas for three factors were above .80 (See Table 45). Each factor scores was estimated by regression methods for further analysis. Finally, research question 3 was assessed by performing analysis of covariance (ANCOVA) to examine the main effects of venture origin on a firm’s resource commitment, strategies, goals, and performances controlling for possible confounding & Lacy, 1999). 48 variables. Differences between firms on covariates such as competition intensity and service age are removed so that the only differences that remain are related to the effects of venture origin on ANCOVA. Method 3, sequential approach, for survey data and unequal cell size was used for the ANCOVA. Strength of association is usually assessed as the percentage of variance in the dependent variables that is associated with the independent variable. A partial eta-squared was used to test the strength of association for each effect. The eta-squared statistic describes the proportion of total variability attributable to a factor. The test for hypothesis support was set at a partial eta-squared of .04 or higher. Homogeneity of variance was assessed using Levene’s test of equality of error variance. 49 Chapter IV RESULTS Descriptives Market and WLIS Profile The Web-based local information services (WLISs) responded to the survey cover 81 Metropolitan markets with a population range of 9 million to 500 thousand. Household income was ranged from average 41,200 dollars to 90,900 dollars. Income per household, estimated number of Internet user, and frequency of response are seen in Appendix 2. As for venture origin of the WLISs, 47 were television station sites, 43 daily newspaper sites, 49 radio station sites, 23 weekly newspaper sites, and 21 Internet venture sites. The average service age was about 36 months (See Table 3). They had average 20,250 visitors a day on their Web sites. Table 3 Profile: Service Age Frequency Valid Percent Cumulative Percent 1994 12 6.7 6.7 1995 36 20.0 26.7 1996 45 25.0 51.7 1997 30 16.7 68.3 1998 28 15.6 83.9 1999 28 15.6 99.4 2000 1 .6 100.0 Total 180 100.0 Respondents also reported to have at least average 7 dedicated staffs to their Web information service. As displayed in Table 4, the WLISs employed average three persons for editorial task, more than one person for design and technical task, 50 and about two persons for marketing. As for quality level of human resources, editorial staff was ranked first (M = 5.6) and design staff received the second highest rating (M = 5.5) by respondents. The quality of human resources is displayed in Table 5. Table 4 Profile: Number of Employees N Min. Max. Mean 8.0. Editorial Staff 177 .00 20.00 2.7839 3.7346 Design Staff 177 .00 15.00 1 .4319 1 .9569 Technical Staff 177 .00 15.00 1.4090 2.0813 Marketing Staff 177 .00 20.00 1.8828 2.8719 Table 5 Quality of Human Resources N Min. Max. Mean SD. Editorial Staff 181 1.00 7.00 5.6243 1.4307 Design Staff 181 1.00 7.00 5.5028 1.5078 Technical Staff 182 1.00 7.00 5.3571 1.4485 Marketing Staff 181 1.00 7.00 4.9558 1.7056 * 1= Very Poor 7= Excellent More than 40% of the WLISs were reported to increase their employees over 50% during last two years. Further 21 % employed their staffs more than 100%. Only 4.6% reduced their employees for the WLIS. Table 6 shows the pattern of change in total employment. Table 6 Change in total employment Frequency Percent Cum Percen More than 50% Decrease 3 1.7 1. 25% Decrease 5 2.9 4. Unchanged 66 37.7 42. 25% Increased 29 16.6 58. 50% Increased 27 15.4 74. 75% Increased 6 3.4 77. More than 100% Increased 39 22.3 100. Total 175 100.0 51 Product Quality and Performance The mean values of product quality assessed by the respondents are reported in Table 7. Editorial quality items were evaluated higher than fimctional quality items. Table 7 shows a rank order of the product quality items. Table 7 Mean of Product Quality Items N Min Max Mean SD. Original content 182 1 .00 7.00 5.5824 1 .5382 Immediacy of the information 182 1 .00 7.00 5.4780 1 .51 13 Depth of the information 182 1.00 7.00 5.3736 1.5917 Breadth of the information 182 1.00 7.00 5.3242 1.4752 Layout 182 1 .00 7.00 5.1923 1 .4722 Aesthetic design 182 1.00 7.00 5.1813 1.5142 \frvidness of images 182 1.00 7.00 5.0604 1.5562 Ease of searching 182 1 .00 7.00 4.8516 1 .6933 Visual effects 182 1.00 7.00 4.7143 1 .6134 Security of transaction 182 1.00 7.00 4.2143 2.0174 Degree of customization 182 1 .00 7.00 4.1484 1.9340 Bulletin board function 182 1 .00 7.00 3.4945 2.0991 As for the importance of performance measures, brand identification was ranked first (mean of 6. l4) and advertising sales growth received the second highest rating (mean of 5.96). E-commerce sales growth (mean of 4.58) and return on equity (mean of 5.09) were rated lowest. Except e-commerce sales growth, market performance was perceived to be more important than financial performance in the current stage of WLIS industry. On the other hand the WLISs responded to the survey were evaluated to make a success in brand identification (mean of 5.16) and market share (mean of 4.86). However all measures of financial performance were below a central point (4.00). This indicates that they made no financial success in their WLIS. Table 8 and 9 show mean importance and success scores in seven performance measures. 52 Table 8 Mean Importance Scores in Seven Performance Measures N Min Max Mean SD. Brand identification 183 1 .00 7.00 6.1421 1 .2005 Advertising sales growth 182 1.00 7.00 5.9615 1.5710 Market share 182 1.00 7.00 5.9121 1.4539 Net profit margin 182 1 .00 7.00 5.4396 1.6468 Return on investment 183 1 .00 7.00 5.3169 1 .7691 Return on equity 182 1.00 7.00 5.0934 1.8107 182 1 .00 7 .00 4.5769 1 .9587 E-commerce sales growth Table 9 Mean Success Scores in Seven Growth Performance Measures Increasing N Min Max Mean SD. Brand identification 181 1.00 7.00 5.1602 1.4764 Market share 179 1 .00 7.00 4.8547 1.5904 Advertising sales growth 179 1.00 7.00 4.2961 1.9736 Return on investment 179 1.00 7.00 3.8603 1.8383 Net profit margin 178 1.00 7.00 3.7978 1.8937 Return on equity 178 1.00 7.00 3.6798 1.8392 176 1.00 7.00 3.0511 1.8586 E-commerce sales growth 53 Financial Commitment All variables entered the equation without violating the default value for tolerance. Further, as Table 10 displays, the highest correlation among the independent variables, between Market Size (log) and Income (log), was .50. Therefore, no evidence of multicollinearity and singularity among the independent variables was found. None of cases had the Mahalanobis distance value in excess of 14.52. This shows no multivariate outliers in the solution. Table 10 Pearson Product Moment Correlations of Independent Variables for Financial Commitment Hypotheses Competition Market Size Income Service age Intensity (log) (log) Competition Intensity 1.000 .005 -.046 .122 Market Size (log) .005 1 .000 .503 -.146 Income (log) -.046 .503 1.000 .085 Service age .122 -.146 .085 1.000 Hla: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to larger quantity of human resources controlling for market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .303 in the direction hypothesized, which exceeds the .200 cut-off point (B = .306, SE = .005). This indicates that a firm’s competition intensity accounts for about 9.2 % of variance in quantity of human resources (log) even when market size and service age are constant. The regression result suggests that as a firm’s competition intensity becomes stronger, the firm tends to employ more people. Table 11 displays the unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients ([3), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. 54 Table 11 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Human Resources (log) B S. E B t Sig. l' pr. sri (Constant) .000 2.237 .030 .976 Market Size (log) .230 .079 .235 2.892 .004 .192 .212 .197 Income (log) -.251 .513 -.039 -.489 .625 .079 -.037 -.033 Service age .000 .001 .169 2.376 .018 .168 .175 .162 Competition intensity .000 .005 .306 4.440 .000 .330 .316 .303 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .414 .171 .153 .3453 To examine the pattern of association, the quantity of four task areas was entered into regression equation. The degree of association in each task area also showed supporting the hypothesis. In particular, the semipartial correlation for the quantity of marketing staffs (B = .329, sri = .305) was found to be stronger than the quantity of editorial (B = .205, sr- = .203) and technical staffs (B = .236, sri = .233) in the relationship of WLIS firm’s competition intensity. The semipartial correlation for the quantity of design staff was .272 (B = .275). In other words, with a stronger competition, WLIS firms appear to employ more marketing staff rather than editorial and technical staff. Table 11-1, Table “-2, Table 11-3, and Table 11- 4 show standardized regression coefficients and semipartial correlations of the quantity of each human resource area on a firm’s competition intensity and other covariates. Table 11-1 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Editorial Staff (log) Coefficients B SE B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) -.390 2.005 -.194 .846 Market Size (log) .154 .071 .181 2.161 .032 .142 .160 .152 Income (log) .000 .460 -.017 -.208 .835 .082 -.016 -.015 Service age .000 .001 .215 2.942 .004 .212 .215 .207 Competition intensity .000 .004 .205 2.884.004 .233 .211 .203 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R7 S. E of the Estimate .343 .118 .098 .3095 55 Table 11-2 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Design Staff (log) Coefficients B S. E [3 t Sig. r pri sr. (Constant) -.694 1.318 -.527 .599 Market Size (log) .149 .047 .258 3.175 .002 .229 .232 .217 Income (log) .000 .302 -.009 -.115 .909 .123 -.009 -.008 Service age .000 .001 .175 2.474 .014 .171 .182 .169 Competition intensity .000 .003 .275 3.983 .000 .298 .286 .272 Model Summary R R" Adjusted R2 S. Eof the Estimate .412 .170 .151 .2035 Table 11-3 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Technical Staff (log) Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sr. (Constant) -1.624 1.558 -1.043 .298 Market Size (log) .148 .055 .222 2.669 .008 .226 .196 .187 Income (log) .161 .357 .037 .452 .652 .148 .034 .032 Serviceage .000 .001 .110 1.514 .132 .110 .113 .106 Competition intensity .000 .003 .236 3.331 .001 .249 .242 .233 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .356 .127 .107 .2405 Table 11-4 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quantity of Marketing Staff (log) Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sr. (Constant) 1.321 1.739 .760 .448 Market Size (log) .110 .062 .147 1.780 .077 .091 .132 .124 Income (log) -.425 .399 -.088 -1.065 .288 -.020 -.080 -.O74 Service age .000 .001 .097 1.349 .179 .109 .101 .094 Competition intensity .000 .004 .329 4.671 .000 .345 .330 .325 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R1 S. Eof the Estimate .373 .139 .120 .2684 56 Hlb: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher quality of human resources controlling for market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was not supported, as the semipartial correlation equaled .173 (B = .175). Even though the semipartial correlation for the relationship did not exceed the cut-off point of .200, the result explains that about 3.1 % of variance in quality of human resources (log) is associated with a firm’s competition intensity in the direction hypothesized. Table 12 displays unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. Table 12 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Quality of Human Resources B S.E fi t Sig. r prl sr, (Constant) -21.456 27.518 -.780 .437 Market Size (log) -2.137 .977 -.185 -2.186 .030 -.134 -.162 -.156 Income (log) 10.756 6.307 .143 1.705 .090 .055 .127 .121 Service age .000 .018 .153 2.070 .040 .214 .153 .147 Competition intensity .148 .061 .175 2.435 .016 .186 .180 .173 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .313 .098 .078 4.2478 H2: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to larger scale of entry into market controlling for market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .290 in the direction hypothesized, which exceeds the .200 cut-off point (B = .293). This shows that 8.4 % of variance in large-scale strategy is associated with a firm’s competition intensity. Thus as a firm’s competition intensity becomes stronger, WLIS firms are likely to conduct larger scale strategies 57 in advertising, specialty services, customer service, and entry. Information from this analysis is summarized in Table 13. Table 13 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Scale Strategy B S. E B t Sig. r pri sri (Constant) 46.966 26.371 1.781 .077 Market Size (log) .000 .937 .007 .081 .935 -.019 .006 .006 Income (log) -6.708 6.044 -.093 -1.110 .269 -.114 -.083 -.079 Service age .000 .017 -.133 -1.806 .073 -.106 -.134 -.128 Competition intensity .239 .058 .293 4.095 .000 .281 .293 .290 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .327 .107 .087 4.0707 Competition and Performance H3: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was not supported, as the semipartial correlation equaled .188 (B = .190). Even though the semipartial correlation for the relationship did not exceed the cut-off point, the result was consistent with the hypothesized direction. About 3.5 % of variance in product quality was found to be associated with a firm’s competition intensity in the direction hypothesized. Table 14 displays the unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. 58 Table 14 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Product Quality Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r prl 5r. (Constant) 5.865 81.638 .072 .943 Market Size (log) -1.663 2.899 -.049 -.573 .567 -.043 -.043 -.042 Income (log) 10.547 18.712 .048 .564 .574 .025 .042 .041 Service age .000 .053 .126 1.677 .095 .161 .125 .122 Competition intensity .467 .181 .190 2.588 .010 .203 .190 .188 Model Summary R R’ Adjusted R‘ S. Eat the Estimate .249 .062 .041 12.6021 H4a: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to stronger emphasis on market performance within its business unit controlling for market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported as the semipartial correlation for the relationship between firm’s competition intensity and emphasis on market performance was .296 (B = .299). The result was consistent with the hypothesized direction. This indicates that 8.8 % of variance in emphasis on market performance is associated with a firm’s competition intensity. A firm’s competition intensity with other firms is positively related to a stronger emphasis on market performance. Table 15 displays the result of the regression analysis. Table 15 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Emphasis on Market Performance B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sr. (Constant) 42.949 28.295 1.518 .131 Market Size (log) .586 1.005 .049 .583 .561 .030 .044 .041 Income (log) -5.819 6.486 -.075 -.897 .371 -.075 -.067 -.064 Service age .000 .018 -.121 -1.637 .103 -.098 —.122 -.116 Competition intensity .261 .063 .299 4.172 .000 .288 .298 .296 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R1 S. Eof the Estimate .324 .105 .085 4.3678 59 H4b: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was strongly supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .333 in the direction hypothesized, which exceeds the .200 cut-off point (B = .336). This indicates that 11.1 % of variance in market growth performance is associated with a firm’s competition intensity. A firm’s competition intensity with other competitors considerably contributed to regression. Thus as a firm’s competition intensity becomes stronger, the firrn’s market growth performance is likely to be better. Table 16 displays the regression result of market growth performance on competition intensity and other covariates. Table 16 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. I‘ pri sr. (Constant) 448.918 236.429 1.899 .059 Market Size (log) 14.551 8.397 .142 1.733.085 .053 .129 .120 Income (log) -102.115 54.192 -.154 -1.884 .061 -.090 -.140 -.130 Service age .193 .153 .090 1.258 .210 .097 .094 .087 Competition intensity 2.515 .523 .336 4.812.000 .355 .339 .333 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R2 S. E of the Estimate .387 .150 .131 36.4964 H4c: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for market size, income, and service age. The semipartial correlation between a firm’s competition intensity and financial performance was .227 in the direction hypothesized (B = .230). Therefore, the hypothesis was supported. In other words, about 5.5% of variance in financial growth performance is associated with a firm’s competition intensity. Table 17 60 displays the unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. Table 17 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 158.464 246.151 .64 .521 Market Size (log) 16.246 8.742 .159 1.85 .065 .127 .138 .134 Income (log) 46.823 56.421 -.071 -.83 .408 -.003 -.062 -.060 Service age .000 .159 -.O16 -.21 .831 -.017 -.016 -.015 Competition intensity 1.714 .544 .230 3.15 .002 .232 .230 .227 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R1 S. E of the Estimate .272 .074 .053 37.9972 H4d: For Web-based local information service, a firm’s competition intensity with other firms will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .207 in the direction hypothesized, which exceeds the .200 cut—off point (B = .210). This indicates that 4.3 % of variance in market share (log) is associated with individual firm’s competition intensity. A firm’s competition intensity with other firms appears positively related to higher level of market share (log). Table 18 displays the result of multiple regression analysis. Table 18 Multiple Regression of Competition Intensity on Market Share B S. E B t Sig. r pri sn (Constant) 1.345 4.644 .290 .772 Market Size (log) -.487 .175 -.239 -2.779 .006 -.268 -.223 -.203 Income (log) .000 1.065 .007 .084 .934 -.095 .007 .006 Service age .000 .003 .275 3.606.000 .341 .284 .264 Competition intensity .000 .011 .210 2.823.005 .242 .226 .207 Model Summary R RZ Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .456 .208 .186 .6919 61 Firm Resources Human Resources As Table 19 displays, the highest correlation among the independent variables, between ‘Organizational Resources’ and ‘Innovation Resources’, was .617. ‘Quality of human resources’ was high correlated with ‘Organizational Resources’ and ‘Innovation Resources’. The inclusion of high correlated variables in the same analysis actually weaken an analysis because they inflate the size of error terms. The resource variables, however, are not redundant because they reflect different measures in four aspects in firm resources. Further, the resource variables are not using their subscale. Therefore, to resolve doubts about possible multicollinearity among the resource variables, each resource independent variable was separately entered into regression equation with a firm’s competition intensity and other four covariates. Mahalanobis distances showed no multivariate outliers in the solution for the hypothesis 5 examining the effects of the quantity of human resources. For the hypothesis 6, Mahalanobis distances also showed no multivariate outliers in the solution with the quality of human resources. None of cases shows the Mahalanobis distance score in excess of 16.31. The variable to case ratio for dependent variables was 1 to 36.6 exceeding the minimum ratio for multiple regression. 62 0802-00 0.6. .0.0 05 .0 28500.0 0. 00002.00 ... 000.. 0.0. .03. ~00. 0.0.- .000. 000.- 000. 0020000.. 00:05:... 0.0. 000.. .03. 30. 000. 00 .. 30.. 000.- 02.05208 30000500000 .00... .03. 000.. 00.. .30. 00 .. 000. v0..- 0020002 000:0... .0 3:000 000. 400. 00.. 000.. 00.. ..000. 000. .00.. 0000 0020002 0005.. .0 0.00000 0 .0.- 000. .30. 00.. 000. . «0.. 000. 0.0..- 000 022$ ...-Na. 00 .. 00 .. .000. um .. 000. . 0.0.- 000. 5.0025 coEEquU 000.- .00.- 000. 00.0. 000. 0.00.- 000.. .000. 600 0E8:_ 000. 000.- v0..- .00.. 0v..- 000. .000. 000.. 80.. 000 .9022 0020800 050.08 m... 4000 m... 0000 4000 02.0505 .000 .0 00:00.5 .0 050000 000 003.3 025000000 0E8... 007. .9022 0000200000 00005000.: 0200001 :50 00. 00.00_._m> 0000000005 .0 000050.000 .5822 8:090 0000000. 2. 032. 63 H5a: The quantity of human resources will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firrn’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was not supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship failed to prove substantially significant (B = .145, sr; = .132). Even if the relationship was positive in the direction hypothesized, only 1. 7 % of variance in product quality is associated with the quantity of human resources (log) after controlling for firms’ competition intensity and other covariates. The quantity of human resources was not related to product quality. Table 20 displays the result of multiple regression of product quality. Table 20 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Human Resources on Product Quality Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 5.532 81.10 .068 .946 Market size (log) -2.803 2.94 -.083 -.951 .343 -.043 -.071 -.069 Income (log) 11.791 18.60 .054 .634 .527 .025 .048 .046 Competition intensity .358 .18 .146 1.895 .060 .203 .141 .137 Service age .000 .05 .102 1.341 .182 .161 .100 .097 Quantity of human resources (log) 4.963 2.71 .145 1.826 .070 .198 .136 .132 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .282 .080 .054 12.5202 H5b: The quantity of human resources will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported, as the relationship between the quantity of human resources (log) and market growth performance was found to be positive (B = .314, sri = .286). This result explains that the quantity of human resources (log) accounts for about 8.2% of variance in market growth performance even after controlling for the firms’ competition intensity and other covariates. Table 21 64 displays the unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. Table 21 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Human Resources on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 446.723 225.445 1.982 .049 Market size (log) 7.033 8.193 .069 .858 .392 .053 .064 .057 Income (log) -93.910 51.709 -.142 -1.816 .071 -.090 -.135 -.120 Competition intensity 1.797 .525 .240 3.420 .001 .355 .249 .225 Service age .000 .148 .037 .539 .591 .097 .040 .036 Quantity of human resources (log) 32.727 7.554 .314 4.332.000 .401 .310 .286 Model Summary R R2 Adjusted R1 S. Eof the Estimate .481 .231 .210 34.8008 To examine the pattern of association, each quantity in editorial, design, technical, and marketing staff was entered into regression equation. The quantity of editorial (B = .274, sr; = .257), design (B = .270, sr; = .246), and marketing staff (B = .289, sri = .268) were positively related to higher level of market growth performance except the quantity of technical staff (B = .191, sr; = .179). There seems to be no difference in the degree of association across three task areas. Table 21-1, Table 21-2, Table 21-3, and Table 21-4 summarize the results of each multiple regression analysis with regression coefficients and model summary. Table 21-1 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Editorial Staff on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S.E B t Sig. r pr. 80 (Constant) 461.740 227.702 2.028 .044 Market size (log) 9.487 8.192 .093 1.158 .248 .053 .087 .077 Income (log) -98.962 52.193 -.149 -1.896 .060 -.090 -.141 -.126 Competition intensity 2.095 .515 .280 4.067.000 .355 .292 .271 Service age .000 .151 .031 .443 .658 .097 .033 .030 Quantity of editorial staff (log) 32.907 8.512 .274 3.866.000 .347 .279 .257 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .465 .216 .194 35.1455 65 Table 21 -2 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Design Staff on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, sr. (Constant) 482.174 228.658 2.109 .036 Market size (log) 7.429 8.341 .073 .891 .374 .053 .067 .059 Income (log) -100.455 52.372 -.151 -1.918 .057 -.090 -.143 -.128 Competition intensity 1.959 .527 .262 3.716 .000 .355 .269 .248 Service age .000 .151 .043 .608 .544 .097 .046 .041 Quantity of design staff (Igg) 47.906 12.990 .270 3.688 .000 .354 .267 .246 Model Summaer R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .459 .210 .188 35.2694 Table 21-3 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Technical Staff on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S.E B t Sig. r pri sn (Constant) 496.687 233.312 2.129 .035 Market size (log) 10.208 8.425 .100 1.212.227 .053 .091 .082 Income (log) -106.856 53.346 -.161 -2.003 .047 -.090 -.149 -.136 Competition intensity 2.178 .530 .291 4.108 .000 .355 .295 .279 Service age .148 .152 .069 .975 .331 .097 .073 .066 Quantity of technical staff (log) 29.407 11.192 .191 2.627 .009 .270 .194 .179 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .426 .182 .159 35.9059 Table 21-4 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Marketing Staff on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, sri (Constant) 396.679 227.221 1.746 .083 Market size (log) 10.206 8.128 .100 1.256.211 .053 .094 .083 Income (log) -85.330 52.163 -.129 -1.636 .104 -.090 -.122 -.108 Competition intensity 1.805 .531 .241 3.397.001 .355 .247 .225 Service age .133 .148 .062 .898 .370 .097 .067 .060 Quantity of marketing staff (lgg) 39.532 9.778 .289 4.043.000 .391 .291 .268 Model Summary R R“ Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .471 .222 .200 35.0183 66 H5c: The quantity of human resources will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was not supported, as the semipartial correlation only equaled .109, which did not exceed the cut-off point. As can be seen in the Table 22, although the relationship was positive (B = .120), the quantity of human resources (log) does not seem to be substantially related to financial growth performance. Table 22 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Human Resources on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, 5r. (Constant) 157.625 245.245 .643 .521 Marketsize (log) 13.371 8.912 .131 1.500 .135 .127 .112 .108 Income (log) -43.686 56.251 -.066 -.777 .438 -.003 -.058 -.056 Competition intensity 1.440 .571 .193 2.519 .013 .232 .186 .181 Service age .000 .161 -.036 -.478 .633 -.017 -.036 -.034 Quantityof human resource (log) 12.512 8.218 .120 1.523 .130 .198 .114 .109 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .293 .086 .060 37.8573 H5d: The quantity of human resources will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was strongly supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .555 in the direction hypothesized (B = .612). This indicates that 30.8 % of variance in market share is associated with the quantity of human resources (log). The quantity of human resources was positively related to higher level of market share even after controlling for the firms’ competition intensity and other covariates. Table 23 displays the result of multiple regression analysis. 67 Table 23 Multiple Regression of Quantity of Human resources on Market Share Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, sr. (Constant) .280 3.64 .077 .939 Market size (log) -.763 .14 -.375 -5.434 .000 -.268 -.409 -.312 Income (log) .591 .83 .047 .706 .481 -.095 .058 .041 Competition intensity .000 .00 .005 .079 .937 .242 .007 .005 Service age .000 .00 .193 3.199 .002 .341 .255 .184 Quantity of human resource (lgg) 1.266 .13 .612 9.662.000 .576 .623 .555 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .718 .515 .499 .5429 H6a: The quality of human resources will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The semipartial correlation between firm’s quality of human resources and product quality, as summarized in Table 24, was .359 in the direction hypothesized (B = .378). Therefore, the hypothesis was strongly supported. This result indicates that a firm’s quality of human resources accounts for about 12.7 % of variance in product quality even after controlling for the firm’s competition intensity. As the quality level of human resources in the WLIS firms becomes higher, product quality is likely to be higher. Table 24 Multiple Regression of Quality of Human Resources on Product Quality _C_oefficients ... B S.E B t Sig. r Pit sr, (Constant) 29.479 76.156 .387 .699 Market size (log) .689 2.736 .021 .252 .801 -.043 .019 .017 Income (log) -1.291 17.568 -.006 -.074 .941 .025 -.006 -.005 Competition Intensity .304 .171 .124 1.779.077 .203 .133 .120 Service age .000 .050 .069 .964 .336 .161 .072 .065 _Q_uality of human resources 1.101 .207 .378 5.315.000 .413 .371 .359 Mgdel Summary j R1 Adjusted R2 S. E of the Estimate A37 .191 .168 11.7358 68 To examine the strength of association on the quality of editorial, design, and technical staff, each semipartial correlation were computed. As displayed in Table 24-1, Table 24-2 and Table 24-3, the quality of design staff (B = .372, sri = .363) had a stronger association with product quality than the quality of editorial staff (B = .292, sr; = .279) and technical staff (B = .320, sri = .314). Table 24-1 Multiple Regression of Quality of Editorial Staff on Product Quality Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r prI Sn (Constant) 40.074 78.856 .508 .612 Market size (log) -.346 2.804 -.010 -.124 .902 -.043 -.009 -.009 Income (log) -.724 18.187 -.003 -.040 .968 .025 -.003 -.003 Competition Intensity .376 .175 .153 2.150.033 .203 .160 .150 Service age .000 .052 .075 1.021 .309 .161 .077 .071 Quality of editorial staff 2.638 .659 .292 4.006.000 .331 .288 .279 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R7 S. Eof the Estimate .374 .140 .116 12.1010 Table 24-2 Multiple Regression of Quality of Design Staff on Product Quality Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pri sr, (Constant) 31.873 76.037 .419 .676 Market size (log) -.236 2.708 -.007 -.087 .931 -.043 -.007 -.006 Income (log) .381 17.495 .002 .022 .983 .025 .002 .001 Competition Intensity .337 .170 .137 1.987 .048 .203 .148 .134 Service age .000 .049 .095 1.348 .179 .161 .101 .091 Quality of design staff 3.167 .588 .372 5.387 .000 .405 .375 .363 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .441 .194 .172 11.7138 69 Table 24-3 Multiple Regression of Product Quality on Quality of Technical Staff Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 2.272 77.441 .029 .977 Market size (log) 7.817E-02 2.777 .002 .028 .978 -.043 .002 .002 Income (log) 624817.774 .029 .352 .726 .025 .026 .024 Competition Intensity .436 .171 .177 2.545 .012 .203 .188 .175 Service age 6.601E-02 .050 .094 1.310.192 .161 .098 .090 Quality of technical staff 2.853 .625 .320 4.565.000 .341 .325 .314 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .401 .161 .137 11.9536 H6b: The quality of human resources will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .277 in the direction hypothesized, which exceeds the .200 cut-off point (B = .291). About 7.7 % of variance in market growth performance was found to be associated with the quality of human resources. This indicates that as the quality of human resources becomes higher, market growth performance is better even when the firms’ competition intensity is constant. Table 25 displays the unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. Table 25 Multiple Regression of Quality of Human Resources on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 504.219 226.56 2.226 .027 Market Size (log) 20.059 8.14 .196 2.464 .015 .053 .182 .163 Income (log) 429.837 52.26 -.196 -2.484 .014 -.090 -.184 -.164 Competition intensity 2.133 .50 .285 4.197 .000 .355 .301 .277 Service age .000 .14 .046 .658 .511 .097 .049 .044 Quality of human resources 2.577 .61 .291 4.184 .000 .317 .300 .277 Model Summary . R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .476 .226 .204 34.9139 7O In particular, the quality of editorial staff was found to be the most important contributor to higher level of market growth performance among the quality levels of four task areas. As can be seen in Table 25-1 through Table 25-4, the semipartial correlation of the quality of editorial staff (B = .281, sri = .269) was higher than the quality of design (B = .194, sr; = .190), marketing (B = .176, sri = .170), and technical staff(B = .169, sri = .165). Table 25-1 Multiple Regression of Quality of Editorial Staff on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 548.987 228.163 2.406 .017 Market Size (log) 18.402 8.112 .180 2.269.025 .053 .168 .150 Income (log) 435.085 52.623 -.204 -2.567 .011 -.090 -.189 -.170 Competition intensity 2.248 .506 .301 4.445 .000 .355 .317 .295 Service age .000 .149 .041 .586 .559 .097 .044 .039 Quality of editorial staff 7.717 1.906 .281 4.050.000 .296 .291 .269 Model Summary R R7 Amsted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .471 .222 .200 35.0133 Table 25-2 Multiple Regression of Quality of Design Staff on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, sri (Constant) 490.182 232.499 2.108 .036 Market size (log) 16.815 8.281 .165 2.031 .044 .053 .151 .138 Income (log) 418.243 53.496 -.178 -2.210 .028 -.090 -.164 -.150 Competition Intensity 2.309 .518 .309 4.454 .000 .355 .317 .302 Service age .158 .151 .074 1.044.298 .097 .078 .071 Quality of design staff 5.025 1.798 .194 2.795.006 .226 .206 .190 Model Summary R R“ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .431 .186 .163 35.8174 71 Table 25-3 Multiple Regression of Quality of Technical Staff on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. 5r, (Constant) 443.169 233.265 1.900 .059 Market size (log) 17.337 8.364 .170 2.073.040 .053 .154 .141 Income (log) -108.992 53.539 -.164 -2.036 .043 -.090 -.151 -.139 Competition Intensity 2.466 .516 .330 4.777 .000 .355 .338 .326 Service age .156 .152 .073 1.030 .304 .097 .077 .070 Quality of technical staff 4.564 1.882 .169 2.425.016 .172 .179 .165 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S.Eof the Estimate .421 .177 .154 36.0062 Table 25-4 Multiple Regression of Quality of Marketing Staff on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pri 5r. (Constant) 457.255 233.064 1.962 .051 Market size (log) 17.202 8.345 .168 2.061 .041 .053 .153 .140 Income (log) -110.118 53.512 -.166 -2.058 .041 -.090 -.153 -.140 Competition Intensity 2.278 .524 .305 4.347 .000 .355 .311 .296 Service age .159 .152 .074 1.047.296 .097 .078 .071 Quality of marketing staff 4.036 1.619 .176 2.493.014 .223 .184 .170 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .423 .179 .155 35.9733 H6c: The quality of human resources will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was also supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship equaled .264 (B = .278), which exceeds the .200 cut-off point. This is consistent with the hypothesized direction. The result indicates that about 7.0 % of variance in financial growth performance is associated with the quality of human resources even after controlling for WLIS firms’ competition intensity and market size. As the quality of human resources becomes higher, financial growth 72 performance is likely to be better even when the firms’ competition intensity and market size are equal. Table 26 displays the result of multiple regression of financial growth performance on quality of human resources. As displayed in Table 26-1 through Table 26-4, the quality of design (B = .259, sri = .253) and marketing staff (B = .215, sri = .208) were positively related to higher level of financial growth performance. However, the strength of association in editorial staff (B = .151, sri = .144) and technical staff (B = .148, sri = .145) were tenuous to predict a firm’s financial grth performance. Table 26 Multiple Regression of Quality of Human resources on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, sr. (Constant) 211.135 237.773 .888 .376 Market Size (log) 21.492 8.543 .211 2.516 .013 .127 .186 .175 Income (log) -73.228 54.850 -.111 -1.335 .184 -.003 -.100 -.093 Competition intensity 1.351 .533 .181 2.532 .012 .232 .187 .176 Service age -.125 .156 -.059 -.801 .424 -.017 -.060 -.056 Quality of human resource 2.455 .647 .278 3.797 .000 .265 .274 .264 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R1 S. E of the Estimate .379 .144 .120 36.6415 Table 26-1 Multiple Regression of Quality of Editorial Staff on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r prI sn (Constant) 212.021 245.508 .864 .389 Market size (log) 18.307 8.728 .180 2.097.037 .127 .156 .150 Income (log) —64.469 56.624 -.097 -1.139 .256 -.003 -.085 -.081 Competition Intensity 1.572 .544 .211 2.887 .004 .232 .212 .206 Service age .000 .161 -.042 -.563 .574 -.017 -.042 -.040 Quality of editorial staff 4.130 2.051 .151 2.014 .045 .147 .150 .144 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. Eat the Estimate .308 .095 .069 37.6751 73 Table 26-2 Multiple Regression of Quality of Design Staff of Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, sf. (Constant) 213.395 238.644 .894 .372 Market size (log) 19.259 8.499 .189 2.266 .025 .127 .168 .158 Income (log) -68.294 54.910 -.103 -1.244 .215 -.003 -.093 -.087 Competition Intensity 1.439 .532 .193 2.706 .007 .232 .199 .189 Service age .000 .155 -.038 -.522 .602 -.017 -.039 -.036 Quality of design staff 6.690 1.845 .259 3.625 .000 .264 .263 .253 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R2 S. E of the Estimate .372 .138 .114 36.7641 Table 26-3 Multiple Regression of Quality of Technical Staff of Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr; sri (Constant) 153.438 244.043 .629 .530 Market size (log) 18.682 8.750 .183 2.135.034 .127 .158 .153 Income (log) -52.837 56.013 -.080 -.943 .347 -.003 -.071 -.067 Competition Intensity 1.671 .540 .224 3.095 .002 .232 .227 .221 Service age .000 .159 -.031 -.414 .680 -.017 -.031 -.030 Quality oftechnical staff 3.991 1.969 .148 2.027.044 .129 .151 .145 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R1 S. E of the Estimate .308 .095 .069 37.6699 Table 26-4 Multiple Regression of Quality of Marketing Staff on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 168.644 241.042 .700 .485 Market size (log) 19.483 8.630 .191 2.257.025 .127 .167 .159 Income (log) -56.597 55.343 -.086 -1.023 .308 -.003 -.077 -.072 Competition Intensity 1.424 .542 .191 2.628 .009 .232 .194 .186 Service age .000 .157 -.035 -.481 .631 -.017 -.036 -.034 Quality of marketing staff 4.928 1.674 .215 2.943.004 .222 .216 .208 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S.Eof the Estimate .342 .117 .092 37.2047 74 Organizational Coordinagon None of cases had the Mahalanobis distance value in excess of 15.92. This shows no multivariate outliers in the solution for the hypothesis 7. No evidence of multicollinearity and singularity among the independent variables was found. H7a: Organizational coordination will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was strongly supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .315 (B = .320) in the direction hypothesized, which exceeds the .200 cut-off point. This shows that a firm’s organizational resources account for about 10 % of variance in product quality even after controlling for the firrns’ competition intensity. Thus a firm’s organizational coordination was positively related to higher quality of product. Table 27 displays the unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. Table 27 Multiple Regression of Organizational Coordination on Product Quality Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sr. (Constant) -29.692 77.791 -.382 .703 Market Size (log) -1.628 2.749 -.048 -.592 .555 -.043 -.044 -.041 Income (log) 14.59417.764 .067 .822 .412 .025 .062 .057 Competition Intensity .350 .173 .142 2.021 .045 .203 .150 .139 Serviceage .000 .050 .118 1.657 .099 .161 .124 .114 grggnizational coordination .916 .200 .320 4.583.000 .344 .326 .315 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .402 .162 .138 11.9485 75 H7b: Organizational coordination will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The semipartial correlation between a firm’s level of organizational coordination and market performance was .279 (B = .283) in the direction hypothesized. Therefore, the hypothesis was supported. About 7.8 % of variance in market performance was associated with organizational resources even after controlling the firm’s competition intensity. The result indicates that as the level of organizational coordination becomes higher, market growth performance is likely to be better even when the firms’ competition intensity is constant. Table 28 summarizes the result of multiple regression analysis. Table 28 Multiple Regression of Organizational Coordination on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pri sri (Constant) 353.361 227.138 1.556 .122 Market Size (log) 14.645 8.027 .143 1.824.070 .053 .136 .121 Income (log) -91.237 51.867 -.138 -1.759 .080 -.090 -.131 -.116 Competition Intensity 2.200 .505 .294 4.354 .000 .355 .311 .288 Service age .178 .146 .083 1.214.227 .097 .091 .080 Eganizational coordination 2.461 .583 .283 4.219.000 .335 .302 .279 Model Summary R RZ Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .477 .227 .206 34.8875 H7c: Organizational coordination will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was again supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .256(B = .260), which exceeds the .200 cut-off point (see Table 29). This is consistent with the hypothesized direction. The result indicates that about 6.6 % of variance in financial growth performance is associated with the 76 firm’s organizational coordination even afier controlling for competition intensity and market size. As the degree of organizational coordination becomes higher, the firm’s financial growth performance is likely to be higher even when competition intensity and market size are equal. Table 29 Multiple Regression of Organizational Resources on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sr. (Constant) 70.837 239.129 .296 .767 Market Size (log) 16.332 8.451 .160 1.933.055 .127 .144 .135 Income (log) -36.848 54.605 -.056 -.675 .501 -.003 -.051 -.047 Competition Intensity 1.425 .532 .191 2.679.008 .232 .197 .187 Service age .000 .154 -.022 -.310 .757 -.017 -.023 -.022 9_rganizational coordination 2.257 .614 .260 3.674 .000 .286 .266 .256 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R1 S. Eof the Estimate .374 .140 .115 36.7293 Innomtion Resources All variables entered the equation without violating the default value for tolerance. Therefore, no evidence of multicollinearity and singularity among the independent variables was found. None of cases had a Mahalanobis distance value in excess of 16.9. This shows no multivariate outliers in the solution. H8a: Innovation resources will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and servrce age. The hypothesis was strongly supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .356 in the direction hypothesized (B = .366). This indicates that about 12.7 % of variance in product quality is associated with firm’s innovation resources even after controlling for competition intensity and service age. Innovation resources are positively related to higher quality of product even when 77 the firms’ competition intensity and service age are constant. Table 30 displays the unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. Table 30 Multiple Regression of Innovation Resources on Product Quality Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) -11.704 76.209 -.154 .878 Market Size (log) -1.603 2.704 -.048 -.593 .554 -.043 -.045 -.040 Income (log) 9.631 17.452 .044 .552 .582 .025 .041 .037 Competition Intensity .259 .173 .105 1.500.135 .203 .112 .102 Service age .100 .049 .143 2.029.044 .161 .151 .137 Innovation resources .800 .152 .366 5.259 .000 .387 .368 .356 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .435 .189 .166 11.7528 H8b: Innovation resources will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firrn’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The semipartial correlation between firm’s innovation resources and market growth performance was .331 in the direction hypothesized (B = .340). Therefore, the hypothesis was strongly supported. About 11 % of variance in market growth performance was associated with the firm’s innovation resources even after controlling for competition intensity. The result indicates that as the level of innovation resources becomes higher, the firm’s market growth performance is likely to be better even when competition intensity is equal. The summary of multiple regression analysis is displayed in Table 31. 78 Table 31 Multiple Regression of Innovation Resources on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sr. (Constant) 399.240 221.510 1.802 .073 Market Size (log) 14.719 7.860 .144 1.873.063 .053 .139 .121 Income (log) -104.704 50.726 -.158 -2.064 .040 -.O90 -.153 -.134 Competition Intensity 1.928 .503 .258 3.836 .000 .355 .277 .248 Serviceage .225 .143 .106 1.570.118 .097 .117 .102 Innovation resources 2.262 .442 .340 5.116.000 .399 .359 .331 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R2 S. E of the Estimate .509 .259 .238 34.1607 H8c: Innovation resources will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was again strongly supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .353 (B = .363), which exceeds the .200 cut-off point (see Table 32). This is consistent with the hypothesized direction. The result explains that a firm’s innovation resources account for about 12.5 % of variance in financial growth performance even after controlling for competition intensity and market size. Innovation resources are positively related to higher level of financial growth performance even when the firms’ competition intensity and market size are equal. Table 32 Multiple Regression of Innovation Resources on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r prI srI (Constant) 105.570 229.836 .459 .647 Market Size (log) 16.425 8.155 .161 2.014.046 .127 .150 .136 Income (log) 49.580 52.633 -.075 -.942 .347 -.003 -.071 -.063 Competition Intensity 1.089 .521 .146 2.088 .038 .232 .155 .141 Service age .000 .149 .000 .004 .997 -.017 .000 .000 Innovation resources 2.409 .459 .363 5.250.000 .398 .367 .353 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R7 S. E of the Estimate .446 .199 .176 35.4446 79 Competitive Strategies Scale Strategy The Mahalanobis distance values for each case showed no multivariate outlier in the solution for the hypothesis 9 and 10. No evidence of multicollinearity among the independent variables was found. All variables entered the equation without violating the default value for tolerance. H9a: For Web-based local information service, large-scale entry strategy will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship equaled .208 (B = .221) in the direction hypothesized, which exceeds the .200 cut-off point. This indicates that a firm’s large-scale entry strategy accounts for about 4.3 % of variance in product quality even when firm’s competition intensity and service age are constant. A firm’s large-scale entry was positively related to higher level of product quality. Table 33 displays the unstandardized regression coefficients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. Table 33 Multiple Regression of Large-scale Entry Strategy and Service Age on Product Quality Coefficients B S.E B t Sig. r pri 5r, (Constant) -25.420 80.660 -.315 .753 Market Size (log) -1.713 2.840 -.051 -.603 .547 -.043 -.045 -.043 Income (log) 1501518389 .069 .817 .415 .025 .061 .058 Competition .308 .185 .125 1.666.097 .203 .124 .118 Service age .109 .052 .156 2.090.038 .161 .155 .149 large-scale entry .666 .227 .221 2.931 .004 .232 .215 .208 Model Summary R R’ Adjusted R‘ S.Eof the Estimate .325 .106 .080 12.3416 80 H9b: For Web-based local information service, large-scale entry strategy will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The semipartial correlation between a firm’s large-scale entry and market growth performance was .327 in the direction hypothesized (B = .346). Therefore, the hypothesis was strongly supported. This explains that about 10.7 % of variance in market growth performance is associated with a firm’s large-scale entry even when competition intensity and service age are equal. The result of multiple regression analysis is summarized in Table 34. Table 34 Multiple Regression of Large-scale Entry Strategy and Service Age on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. Si'r (Constant) 299.782 223.694 1.340 .182 Market Size (log) 14.310 7.875 .140 1.817 .071 .053 .135 .118 Income (log) -80.815 50.998 -.122 -1.585 .115 -.090 -.118 -.103 Competition 1.757 .513 .235 3.426 .001 .355 .249 .222 Service age .291 .145 .136 2.006 .046 .097 .149 .130 Erge-scale entry 3.175 .630 .346 5.039.000 .409 .354 .327 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R1 S. Eof the Estimate .506 .256 .235 34.2270 H9c: For Web-based local information service, large-scale entry strategy will be positively related to the higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship equaled .263 (B = .278), which exceeds the .200 cut-off point (see Table 35). This is consistent with the hypothesized direction. The result indicates that about 6.9 % of variance in financial growth performance is associated with large- 81 scale entry even after controlling for the firms’ competition intensity and market size. A firm’s large-scale entry strategy was positively related to higher level of financial growth performance. Table 35 Multiple Regression of Large-scale Entry Strategy and Service Age on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 38.593 239.545 .161 .872 Market Size (log) 16.052 8.433 .157 1.903.059 .127 .142 .132 Income (log) -29.704 54.612 -.045 -.544 .587 -.003 -.041 -.038 Competition 1.105 .549 .148 2.012.046 .232 .150 .140 Service age .000 .155 .021 .288 .773 -.017 .022 .020 age-scale entry 2.552 .675 .278 3.782 .000 .320 .273 .263 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R1 S. Eof the Estimate .378 .143 .119 36.6523 H9d: For Web-based local information service, large-scale entry strategy will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. As shown in the Table 36, the semipartial correlation did not exceed the cut- off point (B = -.010, sr; = -.010). The hypothesis was not supported. This indicates that there is little association between a firm’s large-scale entry and market share. Table 36 Multiple Regression of Large-scale Entry Strategy and Service Age on Market Share Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 1.416 4.688 .302 .763 Market Size (log) -.485 .176 -.239 -2.761 .007 -.268 -.222 -.203 Income (log) .000 1.071 .006 .074 .941 -.095 .006 .005 Competition .000 .011 .213 2.766.006 .242 .222 .203 Service age .000 .003 .273 3.547 .001 .341 .281 .260 Lafle-scale entg .000 .014 -.010 -.137 .892 -.004 -.011 -.010 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .456 .208 .181 .6942 82 Time of Entry H10a: For Web-based local information service, earlier entry into market will be positively related to higher quality of product controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and scale of entry. As Table 33 displays, the hypothesis was not supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship failed to prove meaningfiil (B = .156, sri = .149). Even if the relationship was positive in the direction hypothesized, only 2.2 % of variance in product quality was associated with a firm’s earlier entry after controlling for competition intensity and scale of entry. A firm’s entry of time was not related to product quality. H10b: For Web-based local information service, earlier entry into market will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and scale of entry. The hypothesis was not supported, as the semipartial correlation only equaled .130 (B = .136), which did not exceed the cut-off point, even though the relationship was positive. This indicates that only 1. 7 % of variance in market grth performance is associated with a firm’s earlier entry after controlling for competition intensity and other covariates (see Table 34). H10c: For Web-based local information service, earlier entry into market will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and scale of entry. The hypothesis was also not supported, as the semipartial correlation only equaled .020, which did not exceed the cut-off point (see Table 35). This shows that variance in financial growth performance is least associated with a firm’s earlier entry afier controlling for competition intensity and scale of entry. 83 H10d: For Web-based local information service, firm’s earlier entry into market will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and scale of entry. The hypothesis was supported, as the relationship between a firm’s earlier entry and market share was found to be positive (B = .274, sri = .260). The result of the regression analysis is summarized in Table 36. This result explains that a firrn’s time of entry into market accounts for about 6.8% of variance in market share even after controlling for competition intensity. Thus a firm’s earlier entry was positively related to the firm’s market share. Product Quality H1 1a: For Web-based local information service, product quality will be positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was strongly supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship was .358 in the direction hypothesized (B = .370). This indicates that product quality accounts for about 12.8 % of variance in market growth performance even when firm’s competition intensity is constant. Product quality was positively related to higher level of market growth performance. Table 37 displays the result of multiple regression analysis. 84 Table 37 Multiple Regression of Product Quality on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 442.323 218.497 2.024 .044 Market Size (log) 16.421 7.767 .161 2.114.036 .053 .157 .135 Income (log) -113.974 50.126 -.172 -2.274 .024 -.090 -.168 -.145 Competition 1.990 .492 .266 4.044 .000 .355 .291 .258 Service age .000 .143 .044 .652 .515 .097 .049 .042 Product Quality 1.124 .201 .370 5.605.000 .419 .388 .358 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R7 S. Eof the Estimate .527 .278 .258 33.7279 H1 1b: For Web-based local information service, product quality will be positively related to higher level of financial growth performance controlling for firrn’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was supported, as the semipartial correlation for the relationship equaled .273 (B = .282), which exceeds the .200 cut-off point. This is consistent with the hypothesized direction. This indicates that about 7.5 % of variance in financial growth performance is associated with product quality even afier controlling for firm’s competition intensity and market size. Thus as the level of product quality becomes higher, financial growth performance is likely to be better even when competition intensity and market size are equal. Table 38 displays the unstandardized regression coeflicients (B), the standardized regression coefficients (B), zero-order correlations (r), the semipartial correlations (sri) and R2. 85 Table 38 Multiple Regression of Product Quality on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pri sr, (Constant) 153.454 236.736 .648 .518 Market Size (log) 17.666 8.416 .173 2.099.037 .127 .156 .146 Income (log) -55.832 54.310 -.084 -1.028 .305 -.003 -.077 -.071 Competition 1.315 .533 .176 2.467.015 .232 .182 .171 Service age -.110 .155 -.052 -.710 .479 -.017 -.053 -.049 Product quality .854 .217 .282 3.930.000 .299 .283 .273 Model Summary R R2 Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .385 .148 .124 36.5433 H1 1c: For Web-based local information service, product quality will be positively related to higher level of market share controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The hypothesis was not supported, as the semipartial correlation only equaled .085 (B = .088), which did not exceed the cut-off point. This shows that variance in market share is little associated with product quality after controlling for competition intensity, service age and market size (see Table 39). Table 39 Multiple Regression of Product Quality on Market Share Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sri (Constant) 1.122 4.643 .242 .809 Market Size (log) -.480 .175 -.236 -2.741 .007 -.268 -.220 -.200 Income (log) .000 1.064 .006 .071 .943 -.095 .006 .005 Competition .000 .011 .197 2.619 .010 .242 .211 .191 Service age .000 .003 .258 3.344 .001 .341 .266 .244 Product quality .000 .005 .088 1.168 .245 .190 .096 .085 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .464 .215 .188 .6910 86 Resources and Competition RQla: Are the effects of firm’s resources on product quality stronger than those of firm’s competition intensity? Firm resources were far stronger than competition intensity in the strength of association with product quality. As summarized in Table 40, all intangible resources including the quality of human resources (difference = .115), organizational coordination (difference = .080), and innovational resources (difference = .117), are stronger contributors to higher quality of product than competition intensity. The difference exceeded the criteria of .02 except the quantity of human resources. For the quantity of human resources (difference = - .002), there was little difference from competition intensity in the strength of association with product quality. Table 40 Comparison of Strength of Association with Product Quality Between Four types of Resources and Competition Intensity Resources Competition Diff. sn sri2 sr- sr-2 R(sr;2)-C(sri2) Quantity of Human Resources Regression .132 .017 .137 .019 -.002 Quality of Human Resources Regression .359 .129 .120 .014 .115" Organizational Coordination Regression .315 .099 .139 .019 .080' lnnovational Resources Regression .356 .127 .102 .010 .1 17* * Difference of Squared Semipartial Correlation between Resources and Competition is above .02 (2%). Rle: Are the effects of firm’s resources on market growth performance stronger than those of firm’s competition intensity? The quantity of human resources (difference = .031) and innovation resources (difference = .048) were stronger contributors to higher level of market growth performance than competition intensity as displayed in Table 41. However, 87 there was no difference between other two resources and market growth performance in the strength of association. Table 41 Comparison of Strength of Association with Market Growth Performance Between Four types of Resources and Competition Intensity Resources Competition Diff. sr- sr.2 sr. sr.2 R(sr-2)-C(sr.2L Quantity of Human Resources Regression .286 .082 .225 .051 .031" Quality of Human Resources Regression .277 .077 .277 .077 .000 Organizational Coordination Regression .279 .078 .288 .083 .-.005 Innovational Resources Regression .331 .110 .248 .062 .048* * Difference of Squared Semipartial Correlation between Resources and Competition is above .02 (2%). RQlc: Are the effects of firm’s resources on financial growth performance stronger than those of firm’s competition intensity? Only the quantity of human resources was found to be weaker than competition intensity in terms of strength of association with financial grth performance. The associations of three resources were stronger than competition intensity. For the quantity of human resources, the difference between resources and competition intensity was only .021. Innovation resources (difference = .105) were far stronger predictor for financial growth performance than competition intensity. Table 42 displays a comparison of the strength of association with financial performance between four types of resources and competition intensity. Table 42 Comparison of the Strength of Association with Financial Growth Performance Between Four types of Resources and Competition Intensity Resources Competition Diff. sr. sr.2 sn sr.2 R(sr-2)-C(sr-2) Quantity of Human Resources Regression .109 .012 .181 .033 -.021* Quality of Human Resources Regression .264 .070 .176 .031 .039' Organizational Coordination Regression .256 .066 .187 .035 .031* Innovational Resources Regression .353 .125 .141 .020 .105" * Difference of Squared Semipartial Correlation between Resources and Competition is above .02 (2%). 88 Organizational Goals RQ2a: What kinds of organizational goals are most likely to be sought through local Web contents service? Principal components extraction with oblique rotation was performed on 17 organizational goal items afier a preliminary extraction to estimate number of factors. Kaiser’s measure of sampling adequacy was used to test factorability. The Kaiser’s measure of .88 showed that there was no problem of factorability on the final solution. Three factors were extracted. The lowest of Cronbach alphas for three factors was .80. These factors accounted for about 61.8 percent of the variance. Loadings of variables on factors, communalities, and percents of variance are shown in Table 43. Variables are ordered and grouped by size of loading to facilitate interpretation. As can be seen in Table 43, the loadings of factor 3 were reflected during the rotation. Thus to interpret the factor 3, caution is necessary to reverse the direction of the interpretation. Component correlations among factors were shown in Table 44. Factor 1 included “Providing high quality information,” “Improving the information product,” “Providing superior information to the community,” “Responding to user's needs,” “Doing the job well,” “Serving the general needs of the community,” “Hiring the best employees,” and “Maintaining high quality transmission standards.” This factor accounts for 37.4 % of total variance. (or = .89). The factor 1 was termed “service quality.” 89 Factor 2 included “Maximizing profits,” “Increasing profit,” “Increasing the gross revenue,” and “Reducing costs.” This factor accounts for 15.9 % of total variance. (or = .86). The factor 2 was named “profitability.” Factor 3 was defined by “Beating the competition,” “Protecting our franchise in the market,” “Maintaining our firm's position in the market,” “Attaining a position of leadership in the business community,” “Maximizing growth of organization.” This factor accounts for 8.49 % of total variance. (or = .80). The factor 3 was termed “business competition.” Principal components extraction with oblique rotation identified three ,3 ‘5 components labeled “service quality, profitability,” and “business competition.” All factors were internally consistent and well defined by the organizational items. Factor scores by regression method were used to examine the effects of three factors. The factor 3 scores were transformed to cancel out the reflection for a unified interpretation with other factors. 90 Table 43 Factor Loadings, Percents of Variance, Reliability For Principal Factor Extraction and Oblique Rotation on Organizational Goal items Pattern Matrix Service Profitability Business Quality Competition Providing high quality information .850 -.128 .000 Improving the information product .845 .000 .000 Providing superior information to the community .825 -.135 .000 Responding to user‘s needs .770 .000 .000 Doing the job well .734 -.101 .000 Serving the general needs of the community .678 .156 .102 Hiring the best employees .570 .000 -.216 Maintaining high quality transmission standards .547 .248 -.162 Maximizing profits .000 .932 .000 Increasing profit .000 .928 .000 Increasing the gross revenue .000 .886 .000 Reducing costs .000 .599 .000 Beating the competition .000 .000 -.833 Protecting our franchise in the market .000 .000 -.808 Maintaining our firm's position in the market .000 .110 -.698 Attaining a position of leadership in the business community .000 .000 -.687 Maximizing growth of organization .192 .130 -.543 Eigenvalue 6.36 2.70 1 .44 % of Variance 37.40 15.88 8.49 Cronbach alpha .89 .86 .80 Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis. Rotation Method: Oblimin with Kaiser Normalization. Table 44 Component Correlation Matrix Component Service Quality Profitability Business Competition Service Quality 1.000 .230 -.441 Profitability .230 1 .000 -.341 Business Competition -.441 -.341 1.000 91 RQ2b: How do firm's organizational goals affect firm resources such as i) quantity of human resources, ii) quality of human resources, iii) organizational coordination, and iv) innovation resources? No relationship was found between organizational goals and the quantity of human resources (log). Three organizational goals do not seem to affect the quantity of human resources (log). Their semipartial correlations for the association with the quantity of human resources were very low as summarized in Table 45. Table 45 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Quantity of Human Resources Coefficients (Constant) 1.336 2.32 .575 .566 Market size (log) .250 .08 .255 2.999 .003 .192 .220 .214 Income (log) -.460 .53 -.072 -.861 .390 .079 -.065 -.061 Service age .000 .00 .217 2.912.004 .168 .214 .208 Goal1: Service Quality .000 .03 -.065 -.812 .418 -.076 -.061 -.058 Goal2: Profitability .000 .02 .080 1.040 .300 .055 .078 .074 Goal3: Business competition .000 .03 -.131 -1.576 .117 -.123 -.118 -.112 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R‘ S. Eof the Estimate .324 .105 .075 .3608 For the quality of human resources, the service quality (B = -.224, sri = -.194) and business competition goals (B = -.228, sri = -. 196) were found to be important predictors. The semipartial correlations of both goals were considerably reduced relatively to zero-order correlations, as can be seen in Table 46. This is due to high correlation (r = .441) between the service quality and business competition, indicating that both variables have a sizable shared variance. A cautious interpretation is also necessary to interpret the standardized regression coefficient and semipartial correlation. Because the organizational items were transformed by a reflected logarithm prior to principal component extraction, the coefficients should 92 be interpreted in the reverse direction. Thus both goals appeal positively related to the quality of human resources even when service age is constant. Table 46 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Quality of Human Resources Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pri ST: (Constant) -11.264 25.622 -.440 .661 Market size (log) -1.868 .920 -.162 -2.031 .044 -.134 -.151 -.135 Income (log) 8.761 5.894 .117 1.486 .139 .055 .111 .099 Service age .000 .017 .224 3.216 .002 .214 .236 .214 Goal1: Service Quality -.965 .332 -.218 -2.906 .004 -.318 -.214 -.194 Goal2: Profitability -.119 .319 -.027 -.372 .710 -.114 -.028 -.025 Goal3: Business competition -1.008 .344 -.228 -2.932 .004 -.301 -.216 -.196 Model Summary R R“ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .466 .217 .190 3.9807 The service quality goal was also observed to be a meaningful predictor for the level of organizational coordination (B = -.412, sri = -.367) and innovation resources (B = -.328, sr; = -.291). The service quality goal accounted for about 13.5 % of variance in the level of organizational coordination and about 8.5 % of variance in the level of innovation resources. A positive relationship was found between the service quality and the level of organizational coordination and innovation resources. The profitability and business competition goals, however, did not seem to affect the level of organizational coordination and innovation resources (see Table 47, 48). The organizational goals appear to affect the level of resource commitment, particularly in intangible resources. Especially, a firm’s service quality goal seems to positively affect the level of the quality of human resources, organizational coordination, and innovation resources. 93 Table 47 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Organizational Coordination Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sf. (Constant) 48.622 26.510 1.834 .068 Market size (log) .502 .952 .043 .527 .599 -.035 .040 .036 Income (log) -6.722 6.099 -.088 -1.102 .272 -.064 -.083 -.075 Service age .000 .017 .081 1.148 .253 .039 .086 .078 Goal1: Service Quality -1.854 .343 -.412 -5.398 .000 -.421 -.377 -.367 60812: Profitability .000 .330 .019 .255 .799 -.080 .019 .017 Goal3: Business competition -.197 .356 -.044 -.553 .581 -.211 -.042 -.038 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .434 .189 .161 4.1187 Table 48 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Innovation Resources Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sr. (Constant) 38.841 34.401 1.129 .260 Market size (log) .583 1.235 .038 .472 .637 .009 .036 .032 Income (log) -2.372 7.914 -.024 -.300 .765 -.005 -.023 -.020 Service age .000 .023 .047 .667 .505 -.015 .050 .045 Goal1: Service Quality -1.929 .446 -.328 -4.328 .000 -.410 -.310 -.291 Goal2: Profitability -.581 .428 -.099 -1.359 .176 -.217 -.102 -.092 Goal3: Business competition -.854 .462 -.145 -1.849 .066 -.320 -.138 -.125 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .449 .202 .175 5.3447 RQ2c: How do firm's organizational goals affect large-scale entry to compete with other firms? Both service quality and business competition goal were associated with the large-scale entry. The semipartial correlation of service quality goal was -.213 (B = -.239) and business competition goal -.221(B = -.257). Both goals were positively related to the large-scale entry into market. Surprisingly, the profitability goal was found not to affect a firm’s scale of entry (B = -.066, sri = -.061). Table 49 summarizes the result of multiple regression analysis using factor scores. 94 Table 49 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Scale of Entry Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. srr (Constant) 61.927 24.617 2.516 .013 Market size (log) .450 .884 .040 .509 .612 -.019 .038 .034 Income (log) -9.510 5.663 -.132 -1.679 .095 -.114 -.126 -.112 Service age .000 .016 -.034 -.483 .630 -.106 -.036 -.032 Goal1: Service Quality -1.020 .319 -.239 -3.198 .002 -.370 -.234 -.213 Goal2: Profitability -.282 .306 -.066 -.923 .357 -.219 -.069 -.061 Goal3: Business competition -1.095 .330 -.257 -3.314 .001 -.389 -.242 -.221 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .470 .221 .194 3.8245 RQ2d: How do firm's organizational goals affect i) product quality, ii) market growth performance, iii) market share, and iv) financial growth performance? As displayed in Table 50, only the service quality goal was positively related to the level of product quality, as the semipartial correlation of service quality was - .243 (B = -.274). For the market growth performance (see Table 51), the business competition goal was found to be a meaningfiil predictor (B = -.338, sr; = -.291). Although zero-order correlation between service quality and market growth performance was -.251, the service quality goal did not contribute to the regression. The relationship between service quality goal and market growth performance was mediated by the relationship between business competition goal and market growth performance. On the other hand, a firm’s profitability goal was associated with higher level of financial growth performance (B = -.292, sri = -.270). The profitability goal accounted for about 7.3 % of variance in financial growth performance. Even 95 though the business competition goal showed a positive relationship with a zero- order correlation of -.294, the relationship was mediated by the profitability goal on the multiple regression (see Table 52). Finally, no relationship was found between three organizational goals and market share as shown in Table 53. Table 50 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Product Quality Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, Si'r (Constant) 36.199 78.324 .462 .645 Market size (log) -.439 2.812 -.013 -.156 .876 -.043 -.012 -.011 Income (log) 4.229 18.019 .019 .235 .815 .025 .018 .016 Serviceage .134 .051 .192 2.617.010 .161 .194 .183 Goal1: Service Quality -3.521 1.015 -.274 -3.470 .001 -.306 -.253 -.243 Goal2:ProfitabiIity -.567 .974 -.044 -.582 .561 -.101 -.044 -.041 Goal3: Business competition -1.016 1.051 -.079 -.967 .335 -.193 -.073 -.068 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .368 .135 .106 12.1687 Table 51 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr. sr. (Constant) 602.633 229.030 2.631 .009 Market size (log) 16.669 8.224 .163 2.027 .044 .053 .151 .137 Income (log) -128.220 52.689 -.193 -2.434 .016 -.090 -.180 -.164 Service age .387 .150 .181 2.577 .011 .097 .191 .174 Goal1: Service Quality -4.818 2.967 -.123 -1.624 .106 -.251 -.121 -.109 Goal2: Profitability .377 2.848 .010 .132 .895 -.109 .010 .009 Goal3: Business competition -13.248 3.073 -.338 -4.311 .000 -.376 -.309 -.291 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R2 S. E of the Estimate .448 .201 .174 35.5828 96 Table 52 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r pr, sri (Constant) 251.977 227.869 1.106 .270 Market size (log) 19.575 8.182 .192 2.392 .018 .127 .177 .161 Income (log) -65.306 52.422 -.099 -1.246 .215 -.003 -.093 -.084 Service age .197 .149 .092 1.317 .190 -.017 .099 .088 Goal1: Service Quality -6.025 2.952 -.154 -2.041 .043 -.261 -.152 -.137 Goal2: Profitability -11.406 2.834 -.292 -4.025 .000 -.358 -.290 -.270 Goal3: Business competition -4.942 3.057 -.127 -1.616 .108 -.294 -.121 -.109 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .453 .205 .178 35.4024 Table 53 Multiple Regression of Organizational Goals on Market Share Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r' prl sn (Constant) 3.073 4.719 .651 .516 Market size (log) -.471 .180 -.232 -2.616 .010 -.268 -.212 -.196 Income (log) -.178 1.085 -.014 -.164 .870 -.095 -.014 -.012 Service age .000 .003 .309 3.933 .000 .341 .309 .294 Goal1: Service Quality .000 .065 .012 .138 .890 -.038 .011 .010 Goal2: Profitability .000 .063 .071 .865 .388 .093 .071 .065 Goal3: Business competition -.112 .069 -.145 -1.635 .104 -.054 -.134 -.122 Model Summary R R7 Adjusted R1 S. E of the Estimate .427 .183 .149 .7075 Venture Origin Organizational Goals RQ3 a: How does variation in venture origin affect firm's organizational goals? A firm’s service quality goal varied with venture origin, as summarized in Table 54, with an eta squared of .047. Venture origin was defined by daily, weekly newspapers, local television stations, radio stations, and Internet ventures. Internet ventures showed higher service quality goals than any other service (see Table 54- 1). The assumption of homogeneity of variance was not violated on this ANCOVA. 97 Table 54 Analysis of Covariance of Service Quality Goal by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 19.339 7 2.763 2.972 .006 .106 Intercept .244 1 .244 .263 .609 .001 Market Size (log) 2.134 1 2.134 2.296 .132 .013 Income (log) .363 1 .363 .391 .533 .002 Competition 12.033 1 12.033 12.946 .000 .069 Venture Origin 8.058 4 2.014 2.167 .075 .047 Error 162.661 175 .929 Table 54-1 Mean Service Quality Goal for Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M 8.0 N TV .000 .93 47 Daily .230 1.16 43 Radio .000 .99 49 I-Venture -.405 .86 21 Weekly .000 .86 23 Total .000 1.00 183 Venture origin defined by five media groups was different in the degree of profitability goal (1]2 = .098). The strength of association for the effect was found to be positive. As displayed in Table 55-1, Internet venture and radio groups had a higher profitability goal than the weekly and daily newspaper groups. There was no violation of homogeneity of variance on this ANCOVA. Table 55 reports the results of ANCOVA of profitability goal by venture origin. On the other hand, the business competition goal did not vary with venture origin (7]2 = .026). The five groups were not different in the strength of the business competition goal (see Table 56). 98 Table 55 Analysis of Covariance of Profitability Goal by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 18.093 7 2.585 2.760 .010 .099 Intercept .000 1 .000 .000 .996 .000 Market Size (log) .274 1 .274 .293 .589 .002 Income (log) .000 1 .000 .003 .953 .000 Competition .727 1 .727 .776 .380 .004 Venture Origin 17.774 4 4.443 4.744 .001 .098 Error 163.907 175 .937 Table 55-1 Mean Profitability Goal for Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M SD. N TV -.128 .886 47 Daily .211 1 .078 43 Radio -.257 .930 49 I-Venture -.256 .968 21 Weekly .651 .947 23 Total .000 1.000 183 Table 56 Analysis of Covariance of Business Competition Goal by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 24.677 7 3.525 3.921 .001 .136 Intercept .21 1 1 .21 1 .235 .629 .001 Market Size (log) . .000 1 .000 .091 .763 .001 Income (log) .000 1 .000 .032 .858 .000 Competition 23.004 1 23.004 25.589 .000 .128 Venture Origin 4.208 4 1.052 1.170 .326 .026 Error 157.323 175 .899 RQ3b: How does variation in venture origin affect firm's i) quantity of human resources, ii) quality of human resources, iii) organizational resources, and iv) innovation resources? Quantity of Human Resources Untransformed data of the quantity of human resources showed gross violations of homogeneity mainly due to the nonnomality of variance as checked at the data cleaning stage. AN COVA of the quantity of human resources, nevertheless, 99 was performed using the untransformed data because of the difficulty in interpreting means from the transformed data. Instead, more stringent eta squared level of .06 cut-off point was applied to the interpretation of the result. With more conservative criteria, the quantity of human resources varied in venture origin defined by five media groups (112 = .252). Table 57 reports the result of the ANCOVA. In particular, the Internet venture and daily newspaper groups employed more people dedicated to the WLIS than the local television, radio, and weekly newspaper groups, as displayed in Table 57-1. Table 57 Analysis of Covariance of Quantity of Human Resources by venture origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 2757.049 7 393.864 12.854 .000 .340 Intercept 32.483 1 32.483 1 .060 .305 .006 Market Size (log) 287.289 1 287.289 9.376 .003 .051 Income (log) 5.254 1 5.254 .171 .679 .001 Competition 157.400 1 157.400 5.137 .025 .029 Venture Origin 1804.384 4 451.096 14.722 .000 .252 Error 5362.236 175 30.641 Table 57-1 Mean Quantity of Human Resources for Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M SD. TV 2.600 1 .569 4 Daily 10.121 8.879 4 Radio 3.295 3.845 4 I-Venture 10.564 8.136 2 Weekly 4.113 4.916 2 Total 5.658 6.679 18 Quality of Hum_an Resources No difference in the quality of human resources was found, as the eta squared of venture origin equaled .028 (see Table 58). Venture origin does not seem to be associated with the quality of human resources. 100 Table 58 Analysis of Covariance of Quality of Human Resources by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 362.624 7 51.803 2.834 .008 .102 Intercept 20.801 1 20.801 1.138 .288 .006 Market Size (log) 174.395 1 174.395 9.542 .002 .052 Income (log) 87.531 1 87.531 4.789 .030 .027 Competition 153.885 1 153.665 8.408 .004 .046 Venture Origin 90.889 4 22.667 1.240 .296 .028 Error 3198.423 175 18.277 Organizational Coordination Venture origin was different in the level of organizational coordination (112 = .072). As displayed in Table 59-1, the Internet venture group has a higher level of organizational coordination than the daily newspaper group. There was no violation of homogeneity of variance on this ANCOVA. Table 59 reports the results of AN COVA of organizational coordination by venture origin. Table 59 Analysis of Covariance of Organizational Coordination by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 357.185 7 51.026 2.688 .011 .097 Intercept 29.012 1 29.012 1.528 .218 .009 Market Size (log) 8.803 1 8.803 .464 .497 .003 Income (log) 3.654 1 3.654 .192 .661 .001 Competition 118.465 1 118.465 6.241 .013 .034 Venture Origin 256.608 4 64.152 3.379 .011 .072 Error 3322.002 175 18.983 Table 59-1 Mean Organizational Coordination for Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M SD. N TV 20.809 4.184 47 Daily 18.442 4.295 43 Radio 20.302 4.423 49 I-Venture 21.907 3.778 21 Weekly 20.565 5.476 23 Total 20.212 4.496 183 101 Innovation Resources As summarized in Table 60, innovation resources varied with venture origin with an eta squared of .091. The Internet venture and television groups showed a higher level of innovation resources than the daily newspaper group (see Table 60- l). The assumption of homogeneity of variance was not violated on this ANCOVA. Table 60 Analysis of Covariance of Innovation Resources by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 861.841 7 123.120 3.963 .000 .137 Intercept 7.625 1 7.625 .245 .621 .001 Market Size (log) 10.170 1 10.170 .327 .568 .002 Income (log) 3.007 1 3.007 .097 .756 .001 Competition 437.736 1 437.736 14.088 .000 .075 Venture Origin 542.793 4 135.698 4.367 .002 .091 Error 5437.464 175 31.071 Table 60—1 Mean Innovation Resources for Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M SD. N TV 32.857 5.705 47 Daily 28.975 5.384 43 Radio 31.892 5.980 49 l-Venture 33.381 5.104 21 Weekly 31.182 8.580 23 Total 31.485 5.883 183 RQ30: How does variation in venture origin affect firm’s i) product quality, ii) market growth performance, iii) financial growth performance and iv) market share? Product Quality Five groups were different in the level of product quality (in2 = .076). As reported in Table 61-1, the Internet ventures were evaluated the highest in product quality (M = 64.71, SD. = 8.98). The radio group (M = 60.49, SD. = 14.63) was 102 ranked the second highest in product quality among the five categories of venture origin. Table 61 summarized the result of the ANCOVA of product quality by venture origin. Table 61 Analysis of Covariance of Product Quality by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 3597.427 7 513.918 3.388 .002 .1 19 Intercept 23.629 1 23.629 .156 .694 .001 Market Size (log) 534.858 1 534.858 3.526 .062 .020 Income (log) 249.283 1 249.283 1.643 .202 .009 Competition 1501.323 1 1501.323 9.897 .002 .054 Venture Origin 2169.155 4 542.289 3.575 .008 .076 Error 26545.954 175 151.691 Table 61-1 Mean Product Quality by Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M SD. N TV 55.938 13.707 47 Daily 58.349 10.179 43 Radio 80.490 14.830 49 l-Venture 84.714 8.979 21 Weekly 54.522 12.783 23 Total 58.552 12.870 183 Market Growth Performance Market growth performance varied in venture origin defined by five media groups (112 = .090). Venture origin accounted for about 9% of variance in market growth performance. Table 62 reports the result of ANCOVA of market growth performance. The Internet venture group (M = 132.52, SD. = 39.98) was ranked first in market growth performance and the daily newspaper group (M = 111.02, SD. = 29.80) was the second highest, as displayed in Table 62-1. 103 Table 62 Analysis of Covariance of Market Growth Performance by Venture Origin Source Adjusted SS dt MS F Sig. Eta Squared Conected Model 61 150.587 7 8735.798 7.022 .000 .219 Intercept 3695.139 1 3695.139 2.970 .087 .017 Market Size (log) 1159.019 1 1159.019 .932 .336 .005 Income (log) 2938.475 1 2938.475 2.362 .126 .013 Competition 25500.196 1 25500.196 20.499 .000 .105 Venture Origin 21506.337 4 5376.584 4.322 .002 .090 Error 217697.043 175 1243.983 Table 62-1 Mean Market Growth Performance by Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M 8.0 N TV 93.065 34.48 47 Daily 1 1 1 .023 29.79 43 Radio 97.979 44.51 49 l-Venture 132.524 39.98 21 Weekly 89.605 36.1 1 23 Total 102.694 39.14 183 Financial Growth Performance Five groups were different in financial growth performance. The strength of association for the effect, however, was relatively weak, with 112 = .043. As displayed in Table 63-1, the Internet ventures (M = .8524, SI). = 39.76) held higher level of financial growth performance than any other group. There was no violation of homogeneity of variance on this ANCOVA. Table 63 reports the results of ANCOVA of financial growth performance by venture origin. Table 63 Analysis of Covariance of Financial Growth Performance by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Conected Model 31418.055 7 4488.294 3.191 .003 .113 Intercept 412.188 1 412.188 .293 .589 .002 Market Size (log) 2726.135 1 2726.135 1.938 .166 .011 Income (log) 600.247 1 600.247 .427 .514 .002 Competition 13054.579 1 13054.579 9.282 .003 .050 Venture Origin 10941 .446 4 2735.362 1.945 .105 .043 Error 246118.723 175 1406.393 104 Table 63-1 Mean Financial Growth Performance for Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M 8.0 N TV 60.085 37.91 47 Daily 59.714 39.77 43 Radio 62.722 39.1 1 49 l-Venture 85.238 39.75 21 Weekly 50.826 33.92 23 Total 62.427 39.05 183 Market Share Even if untransformed data of market share showed gross violations of homogeneity, the ANCOVA of market share was performed using the untransformed data because of the difficulty in interpreting means from the transformed data. Instead, a more stringent eta squared level of .06 cut-off point was applied to the interpretation of the result. Market share varied in venture origin defined by five media groups (112 = .223). Variation in venture origin accounted for about 22.3 % of variance in market share. Table 64 reports the result of ANCOVA of market share by venture origin. As can be seen in Table 64-1, the daily newspaper group showed market share index of 5.47%, Internet venture group 5.42%, television station group 1.40%, weekly newspaper group 1.29%, and radio station group .60% for their Web-based local information service. Table 64 Analysis of Covariance of Market Share by Venture Origin Source Adjusted df MS F Sig. Eta SS Squared Corrected Model 821 .251 7 1 17.322 8.704 .000 .296 Intercept 10.733 1 10.733 .796 .374 .005 Market Size (log) 101.916 1 101.916 7.561 .007 .050 Income (log) 27.930 1 27.930 2.072 .152 .014 Competition 17.360 1 17.360 1 .288 .258 .009 Origin 561.015 4 140.254 10.406 .000 .223 Error 1954.388 145 13.479 105 Table 64-1 Mean Market Share for Five Categories of Venture Origin Origin M 8.0. N TV 1 .404 1 .708 39 Daily 5.469 5.276 39 Radio .604 .676 41 I-Venture 5.420 6.892 1 8 Weekly 1 .289 2.192 16 Total 2.686 4.273 153 Additional Analysis: Intangible Resources The present research also tested the effects of tangible and intangible resources on firm performance even if the hypotheses were not addressed at the research design stage. Hall (1993) explained variation in firm performance by proposing a broad set of organization factors that are intangible. A firm’s unique resources must be difficult to replicate, because they are either tacit or socially complex. Such resources are invisible assets based on learning by doing that are accumulated through experience and refined by practice. Grant (1991) also argued that financial balance sheets are inadequate in identifying and appraising a firm's resources, because they disregard intangible resources and people-based skills. The intangible resources such as the quality of human resources, organizational coordination, and innovation resources are probably more strategically important resources of the firm than tangible resources For the testing of the relationship, tangible resources were operationalized by the quantity of human resources. Intangible resources were defined by three types of resources: the quality of human resources, organizational coordination, and innovation resources. For the intangible resources measure, the standardized scores 106 of three resources variables were combined with equal weighting. The standardized item alpha for the intangible resources scale was .78. No evidence of multicollinearity among the independent variables for the hypotheses was found. All variables entered the equation without violating the default value for tolerance. The highest correlation among the independent variables was .503. None of cases had the Mahalanobis distance score in excess of 18.04. This shows no multivariate outliers in the solution for the hypothesis 9. Pearson Product Correlations between the independent variables are displayed in Table 65. Table 65 Pearson Product Moment Correlations of Independent Variables for Intangible Resources Hypotheses Correlations Market size Income Comp Service Tangible Intangible (log) (log) age (log) resources Market size (log) 1.000 .503* .005 -.146 .192* -.067 Income (log) .503* 1.000 -.046 .085 .079 -.006 Competition .005 -.046 1 .000 .122 .330‘ 223* Service age -.146 .085 .122 1.000 .168 .099 Tangible resources (log) .192* .079 .330* .168 1.000 .133 Intangible resources -.067 -.006 .223" .099 .133 1.000 * Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed). H12a: The efl‘ects of firm’s intangible resources on product quality will be stronger than those of tangible resources. The semipartial correlation of intangible resources was .401(B = .414) while the tangible resources equaled only .103 (B = .113). The difference between two semipartial correlations explains that the strength of association with product quality is found to be different on each resources variable. Therefore, the hypothesis was strongly supported. A firm’s intangible resources account for more 107 15 % variance in product quality than the tangible resources, which did not contribute to the regression. The association of intangible resources was stronger than the association of tangible resources with product quality. Information from this analysis is summarized in Table 66. Table 66 Multiple Regression of Tangible and Intangible Resources on Product Quality Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r sr. sri2 (Constant) -10.268 73.948 -.139 .890 Market Size (log) -1.452 2.695 -.043 -.539 .591 -.043 -.035 .001 Income (log) 800016.962 .037 .472 .638 .025 .031 .001 Competition .159 .175 .065 .907 .365 .203 .060 .004 Service age .000 .049 .084 1.207 .229 .161 .079 .006 Tangible resources (log) 3.881 2.483 .113 1.563.120 .198 .103 .011 Intangible resources 1.983 .325 .414 6.099.000 .455 .401 .161 Model Summary R R1 Adjusted R2 S. E of the Estimate .490 .240 .214 . 11.4080 H12b: The effects of firm’s intangible resources on market grth performance will be stronger than those of tangible resources. The hypothesis was supported. Both types of resources were associated with market growth performance. However, the semipartial correlation of intangible resources (B = .343, sri = .332) was higher than the semipartial correlation of tangible resources ([3 = .288, sri = .261). Intangible resources account for more 4% variance in market growth performance than tangible resources. Table 67 reports the result of multiple regression analysis of market growth performance on two types of resources. 108 Table 67 Multiple Regression of Tangible and Intangible Resources on Market Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r 5r. sri2 (Constant) 406.968 209.428 1.943 .054 Market Size (log) 10.433 7.632 .102 1.367 .173 .053 .084 .007 Income (log) 403.448 48.038 -.156 -2.153 .033 -.090 -.132 .017 Competition 1.296 .496 .173 2.610.010 .355 .160 .026 Service age .000 .138 .022 .346 .730 .097 .021 .001 Tangible resources 30.006 7.031 .288 4.268 .000 .401 .261 .068 Intangible resources 4.990 .921 .343 5.418.000 .416 .332 .110 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R2 S. E of the Estimate .584 .341 .319 32.3086 H12c: The efi‘ects of firm’s intangible resources on financial grth performance will be stronger than those of tangible resources. The hypothesis was strongly supported. The semipartial correlation of intangible resources (B = .349, sri = .338) was higher than the semipartial correlation of tangible resources (B = .094, sr; = .085). A firm’s intangible resources account for more 10% variance in financial growth performance than tangible resources. Even the tangible resources were not related to financial growth performance. The association of intangible resources with financial growth performance was far stronger than the association of tangible resources. Table 68 reports the result of multiple regression analysis of financial growth performance on two types of resources. 109 Table 68 Multiple Regression of Tangible and Intangible Resources on Financial Growth Performance Coefficients B S. E B t Sig. r 3r. sriz (Constant) 117.232 230.234 .509 .611 Market Size (log) 16.826 8.390 .165 2.005.046 .127 .135 .018 Income (log) -53.378 52.811 -.081 -1.011 .314 -.003 -.068 .005 Competition .931 .546 .125 1.706.090 .232 .115 .013 Service age -.110 .152 -.052 -.725 .469 -.017 -.049 .002 Tangible resources 9.748 7.730 .094 1.261 .209 .198 .085 .007 Intangible resources 5.070 1.012 .349 5.008.000 .374 .338 .114 Model Summary R R‘ Adjusted R‘ S. E of the Estimate .447 .200 .173 35.5183 110 Chapter V SUMMARY AND DISCUSSION Financial Commitment The first purpose of the present research was to assess the relationship between competition intensity and a firm’s financial commitment to the Web-based local information service (WLIS). This reflected an important theoretical issue about whether the financial commitment theory is applicable to the monopolistic competitive market of WLIS, since the theory was based on oligopoly markets of daily newspapers and local television stations. Three aspects of financial commitment were hypothesized to examine the claim of the financial commitment theory: the quantity of human resources, the quality of human resources, and large- scale strategy. First, a firm’s competition intensity was positively related to a larger quantity of human resources controlling for market size, income, and service age. As WLIS firms perceive stronger competitive pressure, they tend to employ more people. This is consistent with the results of previous research for newspapers and television stations. The WLIS provides a more comprehensive breadth of product line including banner advertising, premium archives, Web page services, and electronic commerce merchandize which traditional media do not or cannot provide. With a variety of products in WLIS, marketing and sales promotion areas seem to become more essential to achieve higher performance for the firms. This result is consistent with the theory of monopolistic competition (Chamberlin, 1933). In the monopolistic competitive market, 111 advertising is considered an important method by which a firm could help difl‘erentiate its product from the products of other firms (Ekelund, Jr. & Saurman, 1988). Firms entering newly developing markets must difl‘erentiate themselves to survive. Survival is accomplished through product differentiation and advertising (Lacy, 2000). Another interesting point is that competition intensity affects the size of the design stafl‘ more than the size of the editorial and technical stafl‘s. This result is consistent with newspaper research. Kenny and Lacy (1987) found that intense competition results in spending more money on the visual aspects of a newspaper. The visual aspects of WLIS are also perceived to be very critical to WLIS product competition by top management. Second, a firm’s competition intensity was expected to have a strong impact on the quality of human resources since the higher quality of human resources also presents another dimension of financial commitment. It was assumed firms should allocate more money for higher quality people in order to compete with other products. However, there seems to be no strong relationship between competition intensity and the quality of human resources. Considering the conservative criterion of the present research for hypothesis supporting, caution is necessary in rejecting the relationship since the result showed moderate positive efl‘ect of competition intensity (er = .173, B = .175). This moderate effect may reflect a limited factor market of human resources in the WLIS. Even if a competitive environment impacts a firm’s desire to employ higher quality stafl‘, quality persons might not be available on the market. The third hypothesis of financial commitment was also supported. A firm’s competition intensity was positively associated with larger scale conduct in advertising, 112 customer service, specialty products, and large-scale entry into market. As a firm’s competition becomes stronger, WLIS firms are likely to conduct larger scale strategies. The results of three hypotheses confirm the claim of financial commitment theory in developing monopolistic competitive markets. Firms in mature oligopoly markets have abnormal profits to invest in product difl‘erentiation, while WLIS firms are not making abnormal profits. WLIS firms, however, can attract investment capital that gives them money for financial commitments (Lacy, 2000). Competition and Performance The second purpose of the competition hypotheses was to evaluate how competitive industry conditions impact firm performance and product quality. These hypotheses were intended to test the classical connection between market structure and firm performance derived from the industrial organization model. First, intensely competitive WLISs were expected to have higher quality ratings for their products in terms of editorial, aesthetic, and functional quality. However, the result showed only moderate effects for the relationship (St; = .188, B = .190). There are several possible explanations for the moderately positive effects. First, the measure of product quality may not be reflected in all scopes of product differentiation even if higher quality of products means differentiating the product from other competing products. Second, product quality may be more a function of the firm’s resources and capabilities to exploit any given market than the firm’s competition intensity. Second, a firm’s competition intensity was positively related to market growth performance including advertising sales, e-commerce sales, brand 113 identification, and market share, controlling for market size, income, and service age. As a firm’s competition intensity becomes stronger, the firm’s market growth performance is likely to be better. This result suggests that industry conditions considerably impact a firm’s market performance Finally, the hypothesis of financial growth performance was also supported. A firm’s competition intensity has a significant effect on financial growth performance in return on investment, return on equity, and net profit margin. The explanation is that the current WLIS market did not arrived at the equilibrium of market demand and supply because it is still underdeveloped. Competition intensity does not have a negative effect on a firm’s financial growth performance even in the short run. This situation was also found in the effects of competition intensity on market share. A firrn’s competition intensity was also positively related to the market share because of the unique feature of an underdeveloped market. In other words, competition affects the increase of absolute WLIS market size. Figure 3 describes a model of competition intensity on the relationship with financial commitment, product quality, and firm performance based on the results of competition intensity hypotheses. 114 Figure 3 Model of Competition Intensity on Relationship with Financial Commitment, Product Quality, and Firm Performance Controlling for Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age Semipartial Correlation Coefficients Financial Commitment .30 ’ Quantity of Human Resources .17 , Quality of Human Resources COMPETITION .29 ’ Large-scale Entry Strategy INTENSITY .19 P Product Quality Firm Performance .33 I Market Growth Performance .23 + Financial Growth Performance .21 + Market Share 115 Firm Resources The purpose of firm resource-based hypotheses was to provide evidence that valuable and unique firm resources and capabilities provide the key sources of competitive advantage. Four categories of firm resources were examined to verify the resource—based theory: quantity of human resources, quality of human resources, organizational coordination, and innovation resources. Human Resource_s_ First, the quantity of human resources was not related to perceived quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. The finding of this research suggests that staff size has no direct impact on product quality in the WLIS industry. Hiring more people does not guarantee a higher quality of WLIS product. The quantity of human resources had a strong impact on WLIS market growth performance and market share. The quantity of human resources was related to higher level of market growth performance and market share. However, the quantity of human resources was not associated with financial grth performance. This indicates that the WLIS ventures still do not recover their sunk costs for hiring employees. On the other hand, the quality of human resources was strongly related to higher quality of product. Product quality in WLIS seems to be more a function of staff quality than the number of staff. Specifically, the quality of design staff was a more important contributor to higher quality of product than was editorial and technical staff. With a smart design, the capability to motivate customers to 116 investigate WLIS contents is considered to be the most decisive source of product quality by managers in the industry. The quality of human resources was also positively related to higher level of market growth performance controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. In particular, the quality of editorial staff was found to be the most important contributor to market growth performance. In other words, resources to contribute to the breadth and depth of information are more related to the higher level of market growth performance. As for financial growth performance, the quality of human resources had a positive impact. As the quality of human resources becomes higher, financial growth performance is likely to be better even when the firms’ competition intensity and market size are equal. It is important that human quality resources were defined in financial terms. Specifically, both quality of design and marketing staff had a stronger impact on financial growth performance while the quality of editorial and technical staff were not related to financial performance. For financial performance, the quality of marketing staff should be emphasized because WLIS is more business-oriented than traditional media. The results of human resources hypotheses support the notion of Brush and Chaganti (1991), suggesting that the quantity of resources is less important than the combination or quality of resources relative to the opportunity for competitive advantages in a start-up company. Figure 4 summarizes the results of the human resources hypotheses. 117 Figure 4 Model of Human Resources on Relationship with Product Quality and Firm Performance Controlling Competition Intensity, Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age Semipartial Correlation Coefficients Quantity of Human Resources Product Quality Market Growth Performance Financial Growth Performance Quality of Human Resources Market Share 118 Organizational Coordination and Innovation Resources All three hypotheses to test the effects of organizational coordination were supported. Organizational coordination was defined as teamwork within the business unit, coordination between departments, and organizational flexibility. A firm’s organizational coordination had a strong impact on product quality and firm performance such as market growth and financial growth performance. WLIS product activity is more than a simple assembly of design, editorial, and technical resources. The ability to organize and synthesize the productive capacity of human resources appears to be of key importance. The result supports that sustainable competitive advantage involves complex patterns of coordination between people and between people and other resources (Grant, 1991). The hypotheses of innovation resources were intended to examine whether innovation in combining or deploying resources can lead to a competitive advantage, thus superior performance. The innovation resources were defined as innovative ideas, creative marketing, new service development, innovative staff, and firm reputation for innovativeness. Innovation resources were positively and strongly related to product quality, market growth performance, and financial growth performance. As expected in the hypothesis stage, the strength of association with dependent variables was the highest of other resources examined for the present research. Companies that competed based on innovative resources were in the best position to take advantage of opportunities in the rapidly changing WLIS industry. For superior performance, it is essential to have the capability to create a new and innovative applications that others will want to imitate. 119 It is important to recognize the internal connection between organizational coordination and innovation resources. Both firm resources are involved in creating and exercising strategic flexibility (Sanchez, 1995). Dynamic product markets such as Web information service require frequent adjustments in product strategies and coordinating the uses of product creation resources. Thus, organizational coordination can provide capabilities to respond to various demands from a dynamic competitive market. Without organizational coordination and cooperation, change in product strategies could take a longer time and more effort. In other words, the flexibility reduces the difficulty of making an innovational shift in the organization. The uncertainty of the WLIS market requires more of a firm’s strategic flexibility to exploit new market opportunities. According to the results of the hypothesis testing, Figure 5 describes a model of organizational coordination and innovation resources in relationship with product quality and firm performance. In addition, the present research tested the effects of tangible and intangible resources on firm performance. For the testing of the relationship, tangible resources were operationalized by the quantity of human resources. Intangible resources were defined by three types of resources: the quality of human resources, organizational coordination, and innovation resources. The effects of a firm’s intangible resources on product quality were stronger than those of tangible resources controlling for competition intensity. The results are consistent with the argument of resource-based theory. Invisible assets based on learning by doing that are accumulated through experience are more important for product quality in WLIS. A firm’s intangible resources also had a stronger association with market 120 growth and financial growth performance than tangible resources such as the number of employees. Although a firm’s resource-based capabilities are shaped by a combination of tangible and intangible resources, the higher levels of intangible resources seem to determine the capabilities of WLIS firms to build sustainable competitive advantages. Figure 5 Model of Organizational Coordination and Innovation Resources on Relationship with Product Quality and Firm Performance Controlling Competition Intensity, Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age Semipartial Correlation Coefficients Organizational Coordination .32 Product Quality .28 Market Growth Performance .36 Financial Growth Performance .35 Innovation Resources 121 Competitive Strategies The present research assumed that the large-scale strategy would be more appropriate to drive success in product quality and firm performance because WLIS is an increasing return business. A firm’s large-scale strategy was positively related to higher quality of product controlling for firm’s competition intensity, market size, income, and service age. Product quality is a function of a firm’s large-scale strategy including specialty services, advertising, customer services, and large-scale entry. A firm’s large-scale strategy had a stronger impact on market and financial growth performance. The exception to these hypotheses was the lack of a relationship between large-scale strategy and market share. Thus market share seems to be more a function of service age rather than of large-scale strategy. A firm’s earlier entry into market was not related to higher quality of product, market growth performance, and financial growth performance controlling for market size, income, competition intensity, and strategy of scale. There seems to be no pioneer advantage for product quality and firm growth performance. A firm’s earlier entry into market was only positively related to market share. However, growth performance is a more important measure for firm success in an immature industry than current market share. As Covin, Slevin, and Heeley (1999) noted, market pioneers are often outperformed by later market entrants. Kerin, Varadarajan, and Peterson (1992) stated that the overall magnitude of positional advantages accruing to the first mover depends on the comprehensive competitive strategies employed by the pioneer and followers. Thus, the tactics associated with early entry and later entry 122 can have a strong impact on the ultimate effectiveness of the market entry order decision. As discussed earlier, large-scale strategy attenuated the overall magnitude of the first mover’s competitive advantage. In the WLIS industry, without effective strategies such as large-scale strategy and intangible resource commitment, first mover advantage has no effects on product quality and firm growth performance. Figure 6 summarizes the testing results of the competitive strategy hypotheses. Figure 6 Model of Large-scale and Eariy Entry Strategy on Relationship with Product Quality and Firm Performance Controlling Competition Intensity, Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age Semipartial Correlation Coefficients Large-Scale .21 Strategy P Product Quality .33 .26 Market Growth Performance Financial Growth Performance Early .27 ’ Market Share Entry Strategy 123 Product Quality Perceived product quality was positively related to higher level of market and financial growth performance. The finding that quality enhances firm performance is consistent with the premise that customers are drawn to quality products. With loyal customers, WLIS firms have some market power to charge more than market price for their premium services. It is interesting that product quality was not related to higher level of market share. In a mature industry, a firm’s product quality directly impacts its relative market share (Kroll, Wright, & Heiens, 1999). The increasing demand for high- quality products may result in a larger market share. The WLIS, however, subscribes to an immature industry. In an infant industry such as WLIS, product quality does not seem to be directly related to market share. A considerable time frame may be needed in order for product quality to materialize market share. Resource and Competition The first research question was intended to compare the relative strengths of the effects on performance and product quality for two different levels of predictors, market and firm resources. The results suggest that the effects of a firm’s intangible resources are more important than market effects on product quality. The difference in the strength of association was substantial. The results are consistent with previous research about firm-specific effects and market effects on firm performance (McGahan & Porter, 1997; Roquebert, Phillips, & Westfall, 1996; Rumelt, 1991). 124 For market growth performance, the effects of a firm’s quantity of human resources and innovation resources were stronger than the effects of competition intensity and market size. However, human resources quality and organizational coordination showed no stronger effects compared with the effects of competition intensity. The results suggest that firm resources can somewhat better explain the mechanism of market growth performance than can industry conditions such as competition intensity and market size. Market-level effects that promote homogeneity among firms coexist with firm-level effects that generate heterogeneity (Mauri & Michaels, 1998). The results provide evidence of the complementarity between resource-based theory and industrial organization, because the degree of difference was not substantial. In other words, both effects of market and firm should be examined to explain the mechanism of market growth performance. The effects of a firm’s intangible resources were stronger than the effects of industry conditions on financial growth performance. Especially, innovational resources had substantially stronger impacts on financial grth performance than competition intensity. The findings support that a firm’s resource effects are more important than market competition effects on product quality and firm performance, even if a complementarity between resources and market competition effects was found on market performance. Moreover, market effects actually work through a manager’s perceived frame of a competitive market. Porter (1980) argued that a viable competitive strategy is dependent on the manager’s understanding of a competitive market. 125 Organizational Goals The present research identified three organizational goals in the WLIS: service quality, profitability, and business competition. The unique dimension of organizational goals in the WLIS is business competition. The business competition goal was characterized by beating the competition, protecting the franchise, maintaining the firm’s position, and attaining business leadership. The business competition goal reflects the facts that the WLIS firms are concerned not only with the present profitability, but also with their future positions to survive in an emerging market. First, the service quality goal was related to the higher level of intangible resources and large-scale strategy. The goal seems to strongly affect financial commitments to achieve a higher quality of service. As a result, the service quality goal had a positive impact on product quality. The interesting point is that the service quality goal is not directly related to firm performance. Without business orientation, a simple service quality goal does not seem to affect higher market and financial performance. Second, the business competition goal was associated with the higher level of quality of human resources and large-scale strategy. However, unlike the service quality goal, the organizational goal of business competition had a strong impact on market growth performance. Thus, there seems to be interaction effects between the business competition goal and financial commitment on market performance. In other words, when a firm has a stronger goal for business competition, its financial commitments may materialize market performance in the WLIS industry. The 126 pursuit of the business competition goal is more important in the WLIS industry than in the traditional media industry. Finally, the profitability goal was not related to resource commitments, but the goal was related to higher level of financial growth performance. This is a very interesting phenomenon in that firms with a strong profitability goal can achieve high financial performance without valuable resources. Porter (1980) proposed two kinds of strategies for competitive advantages: cost-leadership and differentiation. The resource commitments are related to competitive advantage of differentiation in product and service. On the other hand, having a low-cost position can yield the firm above- average returns in its industry. Cost-leadership is often pursued as a strategy by firms without resources (Chandler & Hanks, 1994). For example, in the initial stage of WLIS market growth, even if a firm did not provide a higher quality of content and services, the firm could achieve above-average return with minimum costs by providing only classifieds. This may be a viable short-term strategy for a small start-up firm due to the current market condition, in which an average WLIS firm has no success in financial performance. Figure 7 illustrates a model of organizational goals in relationship to firm resources, product quality, and firm performance. 127 Figure 7 Model of Organizational Goal on Relationship with Firm Resources, Strategies, Product Quality, and Firm Performance Controlling Market Size, Market Income, and Service Age Semipartial Correlation Coefficients Goal 1 .22 Service Quality 4 Quality of Human Resources .37 \ Organizaticmal Coordination Innovational Resources Goal 2 Profitability Large-scale Entry Strategy .27 Product Quality .23 [A Market Growth Performance Goal 3 Business Competition Financial Growth Performance 128 Venture Origin A firm’s service quality goal varied with venture origin defined by daily, weekly newspapers; local television stations; radio stations; and Internet ventures. Internet ventures pursued higher service goals than any other service. Venture origin also affected the pursuit of the profitability goal. Internet venture and radio groups had a higher profitability goal than the newspaper group. The research question also examined the impact of venture origin on resource commitments. Internet venture and daily newspaper groups had more dedicated staffs than TV, radio, and weekly newspaper groups even if there was no difference in quality of human resources. For organizational coordination, the Internet venture group had a higher level than the daily newspaper group. Internet venture and television groups also showed a higher level of innovation resources than the daily newspaper groups. Thus the Internet venture group was found to have more human resources and higher organizational and innovational resources than other origin groups. In particular, although the daily newspaper group was found to have the same level of human resources as the Internet venture group, it has the lowest level of organizational coordination and innovation resources among the five groups. The next research question attempted to identify how variation in venture origin affects a firm’s product quality and performance. Five groups were different in product quality. Internet venture and radio groups had a higher quality of product than other groups. For market growth performance, Internet venture was ranked first and daily newspaper was the second highest. Market share index varied in venture origin. Daily newspaper held a market share of 5.47%, Internet venture 129 5.42%, local television station 1.40%, weekly newspaper 1.29%, and radio station .60%. Considering the market share and market growth performance, the current WLIS market seems to be characterized by strong competition between daily newspapers and Internet ventures. On the other hand, financial growth performance was different according to venture origin. Internet venture had higher level of financial growth performance than any other group. Thus, although daily newspaper has a higher market share than other groups, only Internet venture achieves financial success in the WLIS industry. There are several reasons for the superior performance of the Internet venture group. First, Internet ventures including independent Internet firms, media subsidiaries, and joint ventures might have greater managerial and strategic autonomy to exploit resources leading to superior performance. In other words, they seem to have operational and market flexibility to react to strategy by competitors and changing environments. The newspaper group may have low flexibility because resources are shared with the parent service. Second, in the Internet venture group, WLIS is defined as an independent business unit with distinctive organizational goals. Thus the Internet venture group does not have supplemental goals to directly protect or help a parent service. The priority of business goal pursuit seems to affect firm performance. Synthetic Model and Implications for the WLIS industry Eight factors were found to be important contributors to higher level of market growth performance: competition intensity, four firm resource variables, 130 large-scale strategy, business competition goal, and product quality. The model of market growth performance in the WLIS is summarized in Figure 8. As can be seen in Figure 9, seven factors were found to affect higher level of financial growth performance: competition intensity, three firm resource variables, large-scale strategy, profitability goal, and product quality. Six factors were important contributors to higher quality of product: competition intensity, three firm resource variables, large-scale strategy, and service quality goal. The model of product quality is showed in Figure 10. Competitive market condition impacts both market growth and financial growth performance. A firm’s human resource quality, organizational coordination, and innovation resources affect the level of both performances. However, the quantity of human resources impacts only market growth performance. Strategically, large-scale strategy was positively related to higher level of market and financial growth performance. However, earlier entry strategy does not affect the level of either performances. Finally, as a firm strongly pursues the business competition goal, its market growth performance tends to be higher. 131 Figure 8 Model of Market Growth Performance in the Web-based Local Information Service Semipartial Correlation Coefficients Competition lntensi .33 Quantity of Human Resources .31 . Market Quallty of Human Resources £8 Growth .28 Performance Organizational Coordinatio Innovation Resources Large-scale Strateg Product Quality Business Competition Goal 132 Figure 9 Model of Financial Growth Performance in the Web-based Local Information Service Semipartial Con'elation Coefficients Competition Intensity .23 Quality of Human Resource .26 26 Financial Organizational Coordination Tr Growth Performance .35 Innovation Resources .26 Large-scale Strategy Product Quality Profitability Goal 133 Figure 10 Model of Product Quality in the Web-based Local lnforrnation Service Semipartial Correlation Coefficients Competition Intensity Quality of Human Resource .32 Organizational Coordination * [gaging Innovation Resources .21 Large-scale Strategy .24 Service Quality Goal 134 There are several implications and suggestions for the WLIS industry in these results. 1. Competitive market condition positively affects the level of market growth performance. Even the competitive market was related to a higher level of financial growth performance. Competition is currently acting to increase absolute market size. Even if there are more than twenty WLISs in a metropolitan market, the market is still underdeveloped. This indicates that many opportunities are open to both entrant and incumbent firms to exploit the market even in intensively competitive conditions. 2. As WLIS firms perceive stronger competitive pressure, the firms tend to employ more people. A WLIS firm seems to perceive that quality of peOple is more important for Web information services. As the result showed a moderate relationship between quality of human resources and competition intensity, however, a firm’s desire to employ higher quality people does not exactly match with real employment. The quality of human resources directly affects financial growth performance. Specifically, a higher quality of design and marketing staffs was found to be very important in achieving higher financial performance. 3. Even if quality of human resources affects firm performance, a firm’s organizational coordination and innovation resources are more critical for firm performance. A firm’s efforts should be focused on developing coordination between design and editorial staff, teamwork within the business unit, organizational flexibility, innovative ideas and innovative staff, creative marketing, and new services. 135 4. Mainstream theory has emphasized the first mover advantage in Internet business. However, there seems to be no pioneer advantage for firm performance in the WLIS. Thus, no firm seems to achieve critical mass to realize economy of scale and scope. Large-scale strategy is critical to achieve higher firm performance than earlier entry. Without large-scale strategy and intangible resource commitment, first mover advantage has no effects on firm performance. 5. There are three main organizational goals in the WLIS firms: service quality, profitability, and business competition. A WLIS firm’s service quality goal is not directly related to firm performance. Only the business competition goal affects a higher level of market performance. If a firm has a strong goal for business competition, its resources may materialize market performance. The pursuit of the business competition goal is very important in the WLIS industry in the long run. The profitability goal seems to be currently pursued by small firms with limited resources. This may be a viable short-term strategy for very small firms. 6. The daily newspaper group holds an average market share of 39%; Internet venture group 38%; local television station group 10%; weekly newspaper group 9%; and radio station group 4% in 81 metropolitan markets. Thus, the current WLIS market is characterized by competition between daily newspapers and Internet ventures. There are distinctive differences in resource commitment and firm performance between the two groups. Even if daily newspaper has the same level of human resources as Internet venture, the daily newspaper group has the lowest level of organizational coordination and innovation resources. This difference of 136 resource commitment results in lower firm performance than the Internet venture group. Daily newspapers should focus on developing organizational coordination between task areas and an innovative organizational climate to achieve financial performance and compete with Internet ventures in the WLIS. Limitations and Recommendation for Future research This study contributes to literature on media economics and management. The results of the present research are consistent with previous media economic research on market structure and competition. It confirms the claim of financial commitment theory even in a monopolistic competitive market. This research elaborated the link between market structure and firm performance by analyzing the effects of firms’ resource commitments, organizational goals and behavior. The results also confirm the argument of the resource-based theory focusing on firms’ uniqueness to explain the performance. The present research reveals how market- level effects are mediated by firm-level conduct for firm performance and product quality. Nevertheless, the research has some inherent limitations. First, this research employed perceptual measures of product quality and firm performance constructs. There is a possibility that the results may be contaminated by the perceptual measures of firm performance. For example, the respondent’s position and task could affect the assessment of the firm’s resources, product quality, and performance. In addition, the statistical results of the present research showed low squared multiple correlations for individual predictor tests because measures with a 137 seven-point scale have a limited amount of variance. A future study could be strengthened by using continuous industry data when the industry becomes more mature. In addition, firm-level measures could be improved by aggregating multiple responses in the same firm. Second, the present research only investigated the firm’s internalized resources including human resources, organizational, and innovation resources. However, the resources available to a firm could include its relational resources owned or controlled by other firms which the firm can access, and market resources which the firm can obtain through market transactions (Sanchez, 1995). Further research needs to develop the effects of relational resources and market resources for sustainable competitive advantage. Third, the nature of the relationship with the parent company may influence the objectives with which the firm is managed, the resources available to it, and determine some operations or functions that it shares with other units (Porter, 1980). The relatedness in venturing refers to the degree to which a new venture shares important resources with the parent firm. Future research needs to explore how the relatedness in venturing affects firm resource commitments, competitive strategies, and firm performance. Fourth, the resource base for the present research focused on Ricardian rents which are based on the possession of scarce and valuable resources. In venturing, Schumpeterian rents may be derived from successful entrepreneurship (McGrath et al., 1996). In a Schumpeterian view, firms develop resources that are unique for a significant period of time although the resources do not yield rents in the long run 138 (Bogner, Mahoney, & Thomas, 1998). In the WLIS business, like in other Internet businesses, Schumpeterian entrepreneurship could have a strong impact on firm performance in the short-run. Finally, the results of the present research reflect the early stage of the WLIS market. The relationships between market and firm variables may change over time. As the WLIS industry matures, the market structure may be more concentrated with a few dominant players. Therefore future research is needed to examine possible changes in relationships between market and firm variables. The product content may also change reflecting better knowledge of consumer demand and usage. This suggests ongoing content analysis to describe the evolving WLIS product. 139 APPENDICES 140 APPENDIX A 1419' h MISSING VALUE ANALYSIS N Mean Std. Deviation Missing No. of Extremes Count Percent Low GL_1 183 6.3716 .9629 0 .0 14 GL_2 182 6.2088 1 .0301 1 .5 15 GL_3 183 6.1585 1.1054 0 .0 13 GL_4 183 5.8525 1 .2861 0 .0 4 GL_5 183 6.2186 1.0251 0 .0 11 GL_6 182 4.8956 1 .7225 1 .5 7 GL_7 183 6.2842 .9055 0 .0 10 GL_8 183 6.1475 1 .0509 0 .0 16 GL_9 183 5.5301 1.5994 0 .0 11 GL_10 183 5.8525 1 .3927 0 .0 7 GL_1 1 183 5.6940 1 .2728 0 .0 3 GL_12 183 6.0546 1.0931 0 .0 2 GL_13 183 5.6175 1.3852 0 .0 6 GL_14 183 5.7049 1 .4974 0 .0 6 GL_15 183 6.3825 1 .0088 0 .0 9 GL_16 182 6.3132 1.0594 1 .5 12 GL_1? 181 6.2541 1.0009 2 1.1 10 GL_18 182 4.0275 1.8311 1 .5 0 GL_19 183 6.0710 1.2316 0 .0 18 GL_20 182 5.5330 1 .4206 1 .5 7 GL_21 183 6.2678 1.1190 0 .0 16 GL_22 183 5.7158 1.3733 0 .0 6 RE_1 182 67.72% 41 .95% 1 .5 0 RE_2 182 61 .68% 38.05% 1 .5 0 RE_3 181 58.70% 40.27% 2 1 .1 0 RE_4 182 55.36% 41 .33% 1 .5 0 RE_5 182 60.30% 37.81% 1 .5 0 RE_6 181 58.29% 38.37% 2 1 .1 0 QOE1 181 5.6243 1.4307 2 1.1 5 QOE2 181 5.5028 1.5078 2 1.1 0 QOE3 182 5.3571 1 .4485 1 .5 6 QOE4 181 4.9558 1 .7056 2 1.1 6 OR1 179 5.2626 1 .3834 4 2.2 1 0R2 181 4.6906 1.5178 2 1.1 4 OR3 181 5.2818 1.4233 2 1.1 1 0R4 181 4.9890 1 .5705 2 1 .1 5 IR1 181 6.0110 1.0593 2 1.1 1 IR2 180 4.8667 1.5259 3 1.6 3 IR3 180 4.8111 1.4094 3 1.6 3 IR4 179 5.0559 1 .3099 4 2.2 1 IRS 179 5.0894 1 .4889 4 2.2 1 IR6 179 5.6480 1.2012 4 2.2 6 ST1 179 5.1285 1 .4689 4 2.2 2 ST2 181 4.0829 1 .7635 2 1 .1 0 ST3 181 5.2320 1 .6704 2 1 .1 0 ST4 180 5.4944 1 .3474 3 1 .6 7 OOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOOO 141 High N Mean Std. Deviation Missing No. of Extremes Count Percent Low ST5 175 3.7657 1.6213 8 4.4 0 ST6 178 4.1629 1 .7439 5 2.7 0 IPF1 182 5.9615 1.5710 1 .5 30 IPF2 182 4.5769 1 .9587 1 .5 0 IPF3 183 6.1421 1.2005 0 .0 16 IPF4 182 5.9121 1.4539 1 .5 7 IPF5 183 5.3169 1.7691 0 .0 0 IPF6 182 5.0934 1.8107 1 .5 0 IPF7 182 5.4396 1 .6468 1 .5 0 SPF 1 179 4.2961 1.9736 4 2.2 0 SPF2 176 3.0511 1.8586 7 3.8 0 SPF3 181 5.1602 1.4764 2 1.1 6 SPF4 179 4.8547 1 .5904 4 2.2 9 SPFS 179 3.8603 1 .8383 4 2.2 0 SPF6 178 3.6798 1 .8392 5 2.7 0 SPF7 178 3.7978 1 .8937 5 2.7 0 SQR1 182 5.3681 1.6086 1 .5 0 SQR2 182 5.5824 1 .5382 1 .5 9 SQR3 182 5.4780 1.5113 1 .5 0 SQR4 182 5.3242 1 .4752 1 .5 0 SQR5 182 4.7143 1.6134 1 .5 0 SQR6 182 5.1813 1.5142 1 .5 2 SQR7 182 5.0604 1.5562 1 .5 1 SQR8 182 5.1923 1 .4722 1 .5 1 SQR9 182 4.8516 1.6933 1 .5 5 SQR10 182 4.1429 1.9444 1 .5 0 SQR1 1 182 4.2088 2.0275 1 .5 0 SQR12 182 3.4945 2.0991 1 .5 0 COM1 182 4.9286 1 .7465 1 .5 10 COM2 182 4.8626 1 .6480 1 .5 8 COM3 182 5.3571 1 .5588 1 .5 0 COM4 182 4.8132 1.8171 1 .5 13 COM5 181 4.1989 1.9219 2 1.1 0 START 180 35.66 18.31 3 1.6 0 NOE1 177 2.7839 3.7346 6 3.3 0 NOE2 177 1.4319 1.9569 6 3.3 0 NOE3 177 1 .4090 2.0813 6 3.3 0 NOE4 177 1.8828 2.8719 6 3.3 0 ECH 175 4.41 1.67 8 4.4 0 USER 153 20051 .26 31292.75 30 16.4 0 gogiofioooooooooooooocooooooooooooooooooo a Number of cases outside the range (01 - 1.5‘IQR, Q3 + 1.5*IQR). 142 APPENDIX B MARKET CHARACTERISTICS (Sorted by market siza) Metro Population Income/hrs. Education Market Size“ Response New York 8,712,127 70,507 75.60 6,882,580 3 Chicago 8,078,169 68,958 81.76 4,951 .91 8 3 Los Angeles 9,297,896 65,408 72.38 3,998,095 3 Boston 5,985,439 68,453 85.05 3.591 .263 2 Washington DC 4,794,945 73,138 89.14 3,188,638 4 Philadelphia 5,055,780 68,216 81.71 2,467,221 4 Detroit 4,424,187 68,676 80.86 2,433,303 3 Riverside, CA 3,185,622 50,963 77.32 2,229,935 1 Atlanta 3,926,961 57,619 84.20 2,159,829 3 Dallas 3,263,944 63,207 82.24 1 .840,864 7 Nassau NY 2,710,066 90,927 89.58 1 .761,543 1 Minneapolis 2,915,783 63,961 92.30 1 .370.418 3 Seattle 2,338,368 66,257 94.24 1 227,643 4 San Jose 1,632,382 81 .423 84.79 1,224,287 1 Baltimore 2,553,142 66,930 77.97 1,148,914 2 San Diego 2,740,077 61 .612 84.68 1,115,211 3 Cleveland 2,256,895 62,560 81.49 1,112,649 4 Portland 1 ,884,047 54,048 88.13 1 .079,559 8 Pittsburgh 2,388,733 59,265 82.41 1 .058,209 3 St. Louis 2,634,547 64,619 76.54 1,053,819 5 Tampa 2,300,477 51,844 81.33 1 ,035.215 2 Denver 2,026,581 56,902 91 .93 952.493 2 Phoenix 2,964,296 50,734 83.59 939.682 3 Norfolk, VA 1 .621 .878 51.723 85.00 932,580 2 Fort Worth 1,628,691 56,170 82.16 918,582 2 Milwaukee 1 ,492,229 64,370 86.55 895,337 1 San Francisco 1,681,221 87,424 85.32 840,611 1 New Haven. CT 1,643,928 86,336 84.37 821,964 2 Columbus 1 ,527,880 56,310 85.97 779,219 1 Austin 1,153,433 48,979 84.46 767,033 4 Salt Lake City 1,311,798 55,109 90.10 764,778 3 Cincinnati 1 .660,813 58,913 80.56 758,992 3 Las Vegas 1 ,424.325 46.945 81 .55 750,619 3 Sacramento. CA 1 .561 .669 56.105 85.85 702.751 1 Kansas City 1 ,752,413 58,444 88.61 700.965 2 Nashville 1,218,637 57,847 81.60 661.720 4 Oriando 1,531,503 51 .035 85.16 638.637 3 143 Metro Population Income/hrs. Education Market Size“ Response New Orleans 1,356,430 56,088 72.51 623,958 1 Oklahoma City 1 .073.175 48.817 85.71 622,442 1 Fort Lauderdale 1,535,978 57,259 83.25 614,391 1 Buffalo 1 ,174.216 59.404 82.16 587.108 1 Indianapolis 1 .573.568 58.488 83.26 577.499 3 Tucson 847,607 44,609 83.40 550.945 1 Hartford. CT 1,125,446 72,230 84.28 545.841 3 San Antonio 1,600,968 51,758 75.43 536,324 2 Honolulu 898,398 78,194 84.45 516.579 2 Charlotte. NC 1,422,683 54,703 77.35 497,939 1 Greensboro. NC 1 208,425 53,814 76.1 1 482.570 2 Providence, RI 91 1 .074 61 .129 76.18 423.649 2 Scranton PA 633,805 52,566 77.69 411.973 1 Louisville 1 .024.323 56.577 81 .07 409.729 1 Greenville. SC 939.973 49.367 70.45 404.188 1 Jacksonville, FL 1 .0461 15 55.270 84.02 392.293 2 Dayton 970.362 57.053 83.67 388.145 1 Tacoma. WA 701 .157 51 .299 89.52 373.717 1 Fresno, CA 905,956 49,749 68.08 371 .442 4 Memphis. TN 1,143,631 59,250 80.52 362.531 3 Albany 884.888 63.864 86.01 353.955 2 Colorado Spring 525.360 47.209 90.01 351.991 2 Omaha 707,575 58,189 90.50 346,712 1 Wilmington DE 576.295 65.579 82.45 345.777 2 Rochester, NY 1 .106,032 65,110 85.07 331.810 1 El Paso 744.633 41 .221 66.31 279.237 1 Little Rock 578.451 52.639 83.62 267.823 5 Bakersfield, CA 669.363 46.987 69.90 267.745 1 Mobile, AL 549.447 46.345 76.19 264,284 1 Columbia 508,984 56,957 83.24 259.582 2 Toledo 619,653 58,172 83.84 258,395 3 Harrisburg. PA 635.454 57.674 82.09 254.182 1 Albuquerque 730.069 51 .288 84.82 240.923 4 Allentown. PA 632.844 57.584 78.39 240,481 4 Akron. OH 699,621 55,544 84.57 230.875 1 Knoxville 693.503 49.626 78.29 221 .921 1 Tulsa 780,085 51 .121 85.61 214.523 2 Sarasota FL 564,807 61 .241 85.41 211,803 2 Fort Wayne 490.336 57.162 84.40 210.844 1 Baton Rouge. LA 594.891 55.169 82.14 208,212 1 Youngstown. OH 601.607 52.299 80.02 180,482 1 Springfield. MA 595.436 56.447 80.44 178.631 1 Wichita KS 526.218 56.291 86.43 157,865 2 Charleston, SC 493,767 57,322 80.23 148.130 1 * Estimates based on responses of WLIS managers. 144 APPENDIX C SURVEY INVITATION E—MAIL LETTER Dear Web Site Manager". We are conducting research that can contribute to an understanding of how the Internet shapes a new model for local information service. The enclosed survey is part of the academic research project being conducted at Michigan State University. Your Web site has been specially selected as a participant in this research. Your response is very important to its success. Your participation is voluntary and your privacy will be protected. We have tried to keep the survey Short so it will take only about 10 minutes to complete. The success of this study depends on your willingness to share your thoughts. You indicate your voluntary agreement to participate by completing and returning this questionnaire. Data will be reported in aggregate and reports of research findings will not associate subjects with specific responses or findings. We will acknowledge your valuable response by providing you with a copy of the final repart. Please click through the following link now or enter the URL in your web browser to complete the questionnaire and submit your response to us. http://www.msu.edul~nohgheeyflssurveyhtm Sincerely. Thomas Baldwin, Distinguished Professor Department of Telecommunication Ghee Noh. Researcher Mass Media Ph. D. Program College of Communication Arts and Sciences Michigan State University East Lansing. MI 48824 517-333-6696 nohgheengilotmsuedu If you have any questions or concerns about participants' rights as human subjects of research, please contact to UCRIHS Chair. David E. Wright (517-355-2180). 145 APPENDIX D FIRST FOLLOW UP E-MAIL Dear Web Site Manager: Two weeks ago you received a survey invitation letter on your local information service on the Web. If you have already completed and submitted the questionnaire. thank you! If you have not done so, then please take a few minutes now to complete it and submit it. We need your answers in order to present a true picture of how the Internet shapes a new model for local information service. We are sure you will find the questionnaire stimulating and interesting to answer. Data will be reported in aggregate and reports of research findings will not associate subjects with specific responses or findings. We will acknowledge your valuable response by providing you with a copy gf the final Lama. Please click through the following link now or enter the URL in your web browser to complete the questionnaire and submit your response to us. http:Ilwww.msu.edul~nohgheeylwi§§ur,htm Sincerely, Thomas Baldwin, Distinguished Professor Department of Telecommunication Ghee Noh. Researcher Mass Media Ph. D. Program College of Communication Arts and Sciences Michigan State University East Lansing MI 48824 517-333-6696 nohgheeyQpilotmsuedu 146 APPENDIX E SECOND FOLLOW UP E-MAIL Dear Web Site Manager. Three weeks ago you received a survey invitation letter on your local entertainment and information service on the Web. If you have already completed and submitted the questionnaire, thank you! If you have not received the letter or have not yet had time to complete it. then please take a few minutes now to complete it and submit it. Please be assured that your responses will be anonymous and aggregated with other respondents. As academic researchers. we rely on the cooperation of people like you in order to find out more about how the Intemet shapes a new model for local information service. We will acknowledge your valuable response by providing you with a copy of 1119 final mmd. Please click through the following link now or enter the URL in your web browser to complete the questionnaire and submit your response to us. Questionnaire: http://www.msu.edul~nohgheeylissumy.htm Sincerely. Thomas Baldwin, Distinguished Professor Department of Telecommunication Ghee Noh. Researcher Mass Media Ph. D. Program College of Communication Arts and Sciences Michigan State University East Lansing MI 48824 517-333-6696 nongheeyggilotmsuedu 147 APPENDIX F WIS SURVEY e would like you to consider the ways that your business unit competes 'th other services in local information services on the Web. These ervices include newspapers. local TV and radio stations. and city guide Web sites. Your business unit may not be a whole organization but a epartment or section involved in production. sales and promotion for Web- based information service. Please respond to the following statements as completely as possible. 1. The following statements represent organizational goals that a business unit may pursue. Please indicate how much importance top management at your Web-based service places on the following beliefs or values by selecting the number that best represents the importance. Not at all important 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Extremely important the well the information to the user's needs the needs of the 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 costs 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 firm and brand 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 revenue transmission standards the service and the best our firm's in the market the best 33333333 33333333 33333333 33333333 33333333 33333333 33333333 148 information leaders our franchise in the market of 2. Think about the relationship between your Web business unit and parent organization or company. Roughly what proportion of your business resources are shared with the parent company? Please circle the percentage that applies to your unit. For example. if you are located entirely in the parent building you would respond 100%. 3. Compared to the top competitor in your city market. how do you evaluate the quality of your employees working on the following areas? Please select the number that best describes your Web business unit. Much Worse 1 2 3 45 8 7 Much Better [IIIZIEIEIEIEIIZI 149 4. To the best of your knowledge. how do you evaluate your organizational routines in the following areas? Very Poor 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Excellent oordination between editorial staff and design Eaff oordination between advertising staff and roduction Staff [Teamwork within our business unit lexibility of organization structure in response 0 the si nals of market 5. The following statements deal with specific resources that a business unit may have. To the best of your knowledge. please select the number that represents how much you agree with the following statements. Our business unit: Strongly Disagree 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Strongly Agree to fresh ideas. creative at the service. in new service a innovative 6. Each of the following items represents different methods by which businesses may compete. Please select the number that best describes the emphasis your business unit has placed on the means of competition. Never Emphasized 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Always Emphasized 150 services limited or markets level of customer service a narrow of services on a Now we w0uld like to ask you a few questions about how your unit conducts on business. Please select the number that best describes your Web business unit. 7. How much importance does the top management at your organization place on the following performance areas? Not at all important 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Extremely important sales sales identification share on investment on 8. How successful was your Web service in the following performance areas during the last 12 months? Not at all successful 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Extremely successful 151 sales e-commerce sales brand identification market share return on investment return on net 9. Compared to the top competitor in your city market. how would you rate your service quality in the following areas? Much Worse 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Much Better of the information content of the of the information effects of of of customization of transaction 333333333333 333333333333 333333333333 333333333333 333333333333 (2 (s f‘ (a (‘ f‘ (a (a F f‘ F F board function Finally. we would like to know a little about your business unit for Web-based information service. 10. At your Web site. how much concern do you have for competition from other local Web sites? Please select the number that best describes your approach. 152 Strongly Disagree 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Strongly Agree 11. Please provide the percentage of lntemet users in your city market. If you are not sure of the percentage, provide your best estimate. City Name 12. Please provide your Web site URL? Http:ll j 13. At what date was you Web site first operational as a service (after any trial periods)? Month I Year 1 14. Please provide your full banner advertising rate on the main page per month. 15. Usually how many people visit your Web site a day? 16. In the following areas, how many full-time employees are employed by your Web site unit? (Please estimate if exact number is not known. Consider two half-time staff as one full- time staff) 153 Editorial staff: { .................................... O Desr n staff ' I a”:.’.-.-.-.-.-.-.-n.-.-.-.-H. .................... .' - . i e l . . . .'.'.‘.’.'I.’.'.'.'.'.'.'.‘J'c‘.'.’I‘.‘.‘.'.‘.’.'Ir‘.'r'.’.'f.‘.'.". Marketing staff: 1 .................................... 17. How much has your Web business unit changed in total employment during the last two years? Please select from one of the dropdowns that best describes your organization. ...... ............................................................................... 19. If you have any comments about or additions to the information provided here, please use the space below. THANK YOU VERY MUCH FOR COMPLETING THIS FORM! Select Submit Survey now to send your responses to us. 154 BIBLIOGRAPHY 155 Bibliography Aldrich, H., & Auster, E. R. (1986). Even dwarfs started small: Liabilities of age and size and their strategic implications, In L. Cummings and B. Staw, eds, Research in Organizational Behavior, vol. 8. San Francisco: J AI Press, 165- 198. Amit, R., & Livnat, J. (1988). Diversification and the risk-retum trade-off, Academy of Management Journal 31(1), 154- 1 65 Andrews, K. R. (1980). The concept of corporate strategy. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin. Babbie, E. (1992). Practicing social research, 6th edition. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth, Inc. Bain, J. S. (1968). Industrial organization. New York: John Wiley. Barney, J. (1986). Strategic factor markets: Expectations, luck, and business strategy. Management Science, 32, 1231-1241. Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120. Bates, B. J. (1997). Television on the Web, 1996: Local television stations’ use the World Wide Web. Paper presented to the Association for Education in Journalism and Mass Communication, Chicago. Baumol, W. J. (1967). Business behavior, value and growth, 2nd edition. New York: Harcourt, Brace & World. Beach, L. R. (1985). Action: Decision-implementation strategies and tactics. In M. Frese & J. Sabini (Eds), Goal directed behavior: The concept of action in psychology. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum. Bogner, W. C., Mahoney, J. T., & Thomas, H. (1998). Paradigm Shift: The parallel origin, evolution, and function of strategic group analysis with the resource- based theory of the firm, Advances in strategic management, 15, 63-102. Brush, C. G., & Chaganti, R. (1998). Business without glamour? An analysis of resources on performance by size and age in small service and retail firms, Journal of Buisness venturing, 14, 233-257. Chamberlin, E. H. (1968). The theory of monopolistic competition. Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press. 156 Chan-Olmsted, S. M. (1997). Theorizing multichannel media economics: An exploration of a group-industry structural competition model, Journal of media economics, 10(1), 39-49. Chandler, A. D. (1962). Strategy and structure: Chapters in the history of the American industrial enterprise. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Chandler, G. N., & Hanks, S. H. (1994). Market attractiveness, resource-based capabilities, venture strategies, and venture performance, Journal of Business Venturing. 9, 331-349. Chandler, G. N., & Hanks, S. H. (1994). Market attractiveness, resource-based capabilities, venture strategies, and venture performance, Journal of Business Venturing, 9, 331-349. Comery, A. L. & Lee, H. B. (1992). A first course in factor analysis. (2nd Ed.) Hillsadale, NJ: Erlbaum. Conant, J. S., Mokwa, M. P., & Varadarajan, P. R. (1990). Strategic types, distinctive marketing competencies and organizational performance: A multiple measures-based study, Strategic Management Journal 11, 365-383. Connellan, T. K. (1978). How to improve human performance: Behaviorism in business and industry, Harper & Row, Publishers: New York. Conner, K. (1991). A historical comparison of resource-based theory and five schools of thought within industrial organization economics: Do we have a theory of the firm? Journal of Management, 17(1), 121-154. Cooper, A. C., G. E. Willard and C. Y. Woo. (1986). Strategies of high performance new firms, Journal of Business Venturing, Fall, 247-260. Covin, J. G., Slevin, D. P., & Heeley, M. B. (1999). Pioneers and followers: Competitive tactics, environment, and firm growth, Journal of Business Venturing, 15, 175-210. Demers, D. P. (1996). The menace of the corporate newspaper: fact or fiction?. Iowa State University Press. Demers, D. P. (1996). Corporate newspaper structure, profits, and organizational goals, Journal of Media Economics, 9(2), 1-23. Dess, G. S., & Robinson, R. B. (1984). Measuring organizational performance in the absence of objective measures, Strategic Management Journal, 5(3), 265- 273. Ekelund, Jr.,R. B., & Saurman, D. S. (1988). Advertising and the market process. San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy. 157 Entman, R. M. (1985). Newspaper competition and First Amendment ideals: does monopoly matter? Journal of Communication, Summer, 147-165. Featherly, K. (1998, November). TV's threat gets bigger on the Web: How the TV networks are competing with papers, mediainfo.com, 16-19. Garvin, D. A. (1984). What does “Product Quality” really mean? Sloan Management Review, Fall, 25-43. Grant, R. M. (1991). The resource-based theory of competitive advantage: Implications for strategy formulation, California Management Review, Spring. 112-135. Gupta, A. K., & Govindarajan, V. (1986). Resource sharing among SUBS; Strategic antecedents and administrative implications. Academy of Management Journal 29(4), 695-714. Hagel, J. (1999). Net gain: expanding markets through virtual communities, Journal of Interactive Marketing, 13(1), 55-65. Hall, R. (1993). A framework linking intangible resources and capabilities to sustainable competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal, 12, 83- 103. Hamel. G., & Prahalad, C. K. (1994). Competing for the future. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Hart, S. L. (1995). A natural resource-based view of the firm. Academy of Management Review, 20(4), 986-1014. Hosmer, A. (1957). Small manufacturing enterprises, Harvard Business Review, 35, 1 1 1 - 122. Kenny, K., & Lacy, S. (1987). Economic forces behind newspapers' increasing use of color and graphics, Newspaper Research Journal, 8, 33-41. Kerin, R. A., Varadarajan, R. P., & Peterson, R. A. (1992). First-mover advantage: A synthesis conceptural framework, and research propositions, Journal of Marketing, 56(4), 33-52. Knight, R. M. (1989). Technological innovation in Canada: A comparison of independent entrepreneurs and corporate innovators. Journal of Business Venturing, 4(4), 281-288. Krasilovsky, P. (1998, January). Market for local Web info services: An in-depth survey of user demand, mediainfo.com, 22-23. 158 Kroll, M., Wright, P., & Heiens, R. A. (1999). The contribution of product quality to competitive advantage: Impacts on systematic variance and unexplained variance in returns, Strategic Management Journal, 20, 375-3 84. Lacy, S. (1987). The effects of intracity competition on daily newspaper content, Journalism Quarterly, 64, 281-90. Lacy, S. (1989). A model of demand for news: impact of competition on newspaper content. Journalism Quarterly, 66(1), 40-49. Lacy, S. (1990). Newspaper competition and number of press services carried: a replication. Journalism Quarterly, 67(1), 79-83. Lacy, S. (1992). The financial commitment approach to news media competition, The Journal of Media Economics, 5(2), 5-21. Lacy, S. (2000). Commitment of financial resources as a measure of quality: Future directions for understanding media quality and performance. Paper presented to the Seminar on Measuring Media Content Quality and Diversity, Turku School of Economics and Business Administration, Turku, Finland. Lacy, S., Atwater, T., & Qin, X. (1989). Competition and the allocation of resources for local television news, The Journal of Media Economics, 3, Lacy, S., & Davenport, L. (1994). Daily newspaper market structure, concentration, and competition, The Journal of Media Economics, 7(3), 33-46. Lacy, S., & Fico, F. (1989). Financial commitment, newspaper quality and circulation: testing an economic model of direct newspaper competition. Paper presented to the Association for Education in Journalism and Mass Communication, Washington, DC. Lacy, S., & Noh, G. Y. (1997). Theory, economics, measurement, and the principle of relative constancy, The Journal of Media Economics, 10(3), 3-16. Lacy, S., & Simon, T. F. (1993). The economics and regulation of United States newspapers. Norwood, NJ: Ablex Publishing Corporation. Lacy, S., & Sohn, A. B. (1990). Correlations of newspaper content with circulation in the suburbs: a case study. Journalism Quarterly 67(4), 7 85-793. Lambkin, M. (1988). Order of entry and performance in new markets. Strategic Management Journal, 9, 127-140. Lawless, M. W., Bergh, D. D., & Wilsted, W. D. (1989). Performance variations among strategic group members: An examination of individual firm capabilities, Journal of Management 15(4), 649-664. 159 Litman, B., & Bridges, Janet. (1986). An economic analysis of daily newspaper performance, Newspaper Research Journal, 7(3), 9-26. MacGrath, R. G., Tsai, M. H., Venkatraman, S., & MacMillan, I. C. (1996). Innovation, competitive advantage and rent: A model and test. Management Science, 42, 389-403. MacMillan, I. C. and D. L. Day. (1987). Corporate ventures into industrial markets: Dynamics of aggressive entry, Journal of Business Venturing, 2(1), 29-40. Mascarenhas, B. (1997). The order and size of entry into international markets, Journal of Business Venturing, 12, 287-299. Marris, R. (1964). The economic theory of “managerial” capitalism. New York: The Free Press of Glencoe. Maslow, A. H. (1970). Motivation and personality. 2nd edition. New York: Harper & Row. Mason, E. S. (1957). Economic concentration and the monopoly problem. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Mata, F. J ., Fuerst, W. L. & Barney, J. B. (1995). Information technology and sustained competitive advantage: A resource-based analysis, MIS Quarterly, 19(4), 487-505. Mauri, A. J., & Michaels (1998), members: An examination of individual firm capability, Journal of Management, 15(4), 649. McDougall, P. P., & Robinson, R. B., Jr. (1990). New venture strategies: An empirical identification of eight “archetypes” of competitive strategies for entry, Strategic Management Journal, 11(6), 447-468. McDougall, P. P., & Oviatt, B. M. (1996). New venture internationalization, strategic change, and performance: A follow-up study, Journal of Business Venturing, 11, 23-40. McGahan, A. (1998). Firm and industry effects within strategic management: An empirical examination, Strategic Management Journal, 19, 211-219. McGahan, A., & Porter, M. (1997). How much does industry matter, really? Strategic Management Journal, 10(3), 199-210. Miller, A., & Camp, B. (1985). Exploring determinants of success in corporate ventures, Journal of Business Venturing, 1(1), 87-105. 160 Miller, A., Spann, M.S., & Lerner, L. (1991). Competitive advantages in new corporate venture: the impact of resource sharing and reporting level. Journal of Business Venturing, 6(5), 33 5-3 50. Mitchell, W. (1991). Dual clocks: Entry order influences on incumbent market share and survival when specialized assets retain their value. Strategic Management Journal 12, 85-100. Mosakowski, E. (1993). A resource-based perspective on the dynamic strategy performance relationship: An empirical examination of the focus and differentiation strategies in entrepreneurial firms, Journal of Management 19(4), 819-839. Murphy, K. R., & Cleveland, J. N. (1995). Understanding performance appraisal: Social, organizational and goal-based perspectives. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage. Nielson, J. (1998). What is "usability"? Available http://www.zdnet.com/devhead/ filters/usability/. Nixon, R. B., & Jones, R. L. (1956). The content of competitive vs. non-competitive newspapers, Journalism Quarterly, 33, 299-314. Nunnally, J. C. (1978). Psychometric theory (2nd ed. ). New York: McGraw-Hill. Oster, S. M. (1994). Modern competitive analysis. New York: Oxford University Press. Outing, S. (1999, October 13). Old-media companies need to stop just following, E & P Online, available at http://www.editorandpublisher.com/ephome/news/newshtm /stop/st101399.htm. Palepu, K. (1985). Diversification strategy, profit performance and the entropy measure, Strategic Management Journal, 6(3):239-255. Penrose, E. (1959). The theory of growth of the firm. New York: John Wiley and Sons Pedhazur, E. J. (1982). Multiple regression in behavioral research: Explanation and Prediction, 2nd Edition. Forth Worth, TX: Harcourt Brace College Publishers. Peteraf, M. A. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive advantage: A resource-based view, Strategic Management Journal, 14(3), 179-192. Picard, R. G. (1989). Media economics: concepts and issues, Sage : Newbury Park. 161 Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York: Free Press. Priem, R. L., Rasheed, A. M., & Kotulic, A. G. (1995). Rationality in strategic decision processes, environmental dynamism and firm performance, Journal of Management, 21(5), 913-929. Prisuta, R. H. (1979). Local television news as an oligopolistic industry: A pilot study, Journal of Broadcasting, 23, 321-32. Rencher, A. C. (1995). Methods of multivariate analysis. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Reed, R., & DeFillippi, R. (1990). Causal ambiguity, barriers to imitation, and sustainable competitive advantage, Academy of Management Review, 15, 88- 102. Reeves, C. A., & Bednar, D. A. (1994). Defining quality: Alternatives and implications, Academy of Managements Review, 19(30, 419-445. Rhea, J. W. (1970). An investigation of relationships among specified variables in the management of television stations. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Ohio University. Robinson, R. B., Jr., & Pearce, J. A. (1988). Planned patterns of strategic behavior and their relationship to business unit performance, Strategic Management Journal, 9(1), 43-60. Robinson, W. T., & Fornell, C. (1985). Sources of market pioneer advantages in consumer goods industries. Journal of Marketing Research, 22, 86-94. Roquebert, J. A., Phillips, R. L., & Westfall, P. A. (1996). Markets vs. management: What “drives” profitability? Strategic Management Journal, 17(8), 653-664. Runett, R. (1998). Building the better online directory, The Digital Edge, available at httpzwww. Rumelt, R. P. (1974). Strategy. structure, and economic performance. Harvard University Press: Boston. Rumelt, R. P. (1982). Diversification strategy and profitability, Strategic Management Journal, 3(4), 359-369. Rumelt, R. P. (1991). How much does industry matter? Strategic Management Journal, 12(3), 167-185. Sanchez, R. (1995). Strategic flexibility in product competition, Strategic Management Journal, 16(2), 135-159. 162 Shaver, M. A., & Lacy, S. (1999). The impact of intermedia and newspaper competition on advertising linage in daily newspapers, Journalism and Mass Communication Quarterly, 76(4). 729-744. Shrader, R. C., & Simon, M. (1997). Corporate versus independent new ventures: resource, strategy, and performance difference, Journal of Business Venturing, 12, 47-66. Shrader, R. C., & Simon, M. (1997). Corporate versus independent new ventures: Resource, strategy, and performance differences. Journal of Business Venturing, 12, 47-66. Sorrentino, M., & Williams, M. L. (1995). Relatedness and corporate venturing: Does it really matter? Journal of Business Venturing, 10, 59-73. Schwartz, E. I. (1996). Advertising Webonomics 101, Wired 4.02 Available at http://vip. hotwired. com/ivired/4. 02/‘webonomics. html. Sullivan, C. (November, 1998). Weeklies to the Web: Clusters are the key, mediainfo.com, 22-24. Tabachnick, B. G., & Fidell, L. S. (1996). Using Multivariate Statistics, Third Edition. New York: HarperCollins College Publishers. Tsai, W. M., MacMillan, I. C., & Low, M. B. (1991). Effects of strategy and environment on corporate venture success in industrial markets. Journal of Business Venturing 6, 9-28. Varian, H. R. (1996). Intermediate microeconomics: a modern approach, Fourth edition. New York: W. W. Norton & Company. Venkatramna, N., & Ramnujam, V. (1987). Measurement of business economic performance: An examination of method convergence, Journal of Management, 13(1), 109-122. Venkataraman, S., & Low, M. B. (1994). The effects of liabilities of age ad size on autonomous sub-units of established in the steel distribution industry. Journal of Business Venturing, 9(3), 189-204. Whinston, A. B., Stahl, D. O., & Choi, S. Y. (1997). The economics of electronic commerce: The essential economics of doing business in the electronic marketplace. Indianapolis, IN: Macmillan Technical Publishing. Zahra, S. A. (1996). Technology strategy and new venture performance: A study of corporate-sponsored and independent biotechnology ventures, Journal of Business Venturing, 11, 289-321. 163 Zahra, S. A., Nash, S., & Bickford, D. (1995). Transforming technological pioneering into competitive advantage, Academy of Management Executive 9, 17-3 1. 164