u..n-- {bk—9...: .; . 3 x. a. it... 5.31;". . m5. “.3. P J's 3:. S: n‘ u, M. 338.... a 1.“. 3PM? . 5%.»qu 43...}; IIV... . uraniohwmul: ‘I...Ih¢ V. ..s.....&. ‘5... 3,3,5 .. V: II. H. 10?... . V t! 9.3:.le . t. r. .. Law ‘3 97de9qu i... . RT. a...» ma. .. , ‘29.)": . . . 3...}. .32?!an ; a: , . . £00.... fighhnfifi. c, ‘l.’{‘§.t I” ‘ - Sioi-.‘I"I p; ' ~£ - lizav 31.1.”..Ovldhra'd‘i 1-" at in... .i :1 ”usalhr . a. ”in." h. .1». .A...SOJJ«.th—l. as . 1.35.7? 1: ‘..w’.flwaafil§alflrnnn 9 3| .1 (a... . 4‘1 .... 394.....11 t... iii-El... . “H t. . . I? . I ‘EIi: I 6.9;..- .5 I . i.— it??? t’vtl..:|§§.§ —2‘.“>¢N.‘II 1%” In. w .3930 1051...! ‘l I. g"!ul".l’n 5.1%.». Juxhufihuuafii . -511"..th II I: l3h..$§ .38 gut-Vaihklualii It!!! 43% .Ilnv.....fln.u.. :Lnngn...1.mr .. {at 3.. gluin$>auiil3511i 92.17:”; “bunn- ii:i..n n .9531} ix“. 0... 11.. I .320 Ont. .fi 1. irmunuuhhsix 3.; a... 3..ka $.51. V x .33“? (3 ”Mn. .. I; 3.1.... i: , ‘ ‘ 3.1(V . ‘41 ,Il , (a: 15...; . £333? i , 4; 2:33.? 3 3%.. 3. V i , 3 Wfiflww“! .1} 12' 7:3 If s u. , . .r intuit. .. , Envy: h... 24“..“ £5.81 . .tathanmwie h. . ’ "fi'fioflfio 5ogla '5‘. I g»: i: . :‘ISI hr :5 .32 x. .l. 3.». 33.4.7133: $3.22!...ng jut§fflwupi I . . .i..oi\nfl.i\x..;..I.Y.?€..?._.).llao‘t If trifle. .t... «it. a at.) viii-fixtrilxxnummwflfl 13. I... {4.5;}. :1 :iziitiii.) . 3:3: ‘93.... hr? ti. I}.L.€.r¢hb1hit..n’Vu.-hlld ‘Sttr.¢31¢ i§ilol.‘ . IX .. (4.. 11...)... l; . THESIS jg} (- LiBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled Mixed Signals: Incentive Structures and Party Strategies in Mixed Electoral Sys tems presented by Erik S. Herron has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in filiticalicience @m V Major professor 8/1/00 Date_ MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0- 12771 PLACE IN REI'URN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE We? 4021102 111w W.“ MIXED SIGNALS: INCENTIVE STRUCTURES AND PARTY STRATEGIES IN MIXED ELECTORAL SYSTEMS By Erik S. Herron A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Political Science 2000 MIXED SK? 2. NC 0’16?” :15.“ .v S!- S‘ .fhnqn mr P U, len‘: “"Mn V n\v 2,. 1N v I\U . ABSTRACT MIXED SIGNALS: INCENTIVE STRUCTURES AND PARTY STRATEGIES IN MIXED ELECTORAL SYSTEMS By Erik S. Herron Institutional designers have recently shown a preference for mixed electoral systems, combining proportional representation (PR) and single member district systems (SMD) into a single election. Underlying this choice has been a belief that Duverger’s Propositions would apply to the individual components of the system. However, the unique features of mixed systems undermine the application of standard analytical approaches. The strategic incentives influencing party strategies are rooted in contamination effects. Contamination is the interaction between PR and SMD components of mixed systems that affects the decision-making of voters, contributors, candidates and parties. While existing scholarship suggests that political actors compartmentalize the PR and SMD sections, there is strong evidence of interaction. This dissertation assesses contamination effects with data from nine mixed systems, but focuses on data from Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine. The empirical analysis produces three major findings: the mechanical effect in mixed systems is more forgiving to marginal parties than the mechanical effect in SMD; parties tend to participate in the whole mixed system, contingent upon resources; 27:89.10 can A3313??? :4; UKIEI‘E den, 39.813; 5:73 “ETAP‘ A. l ”‘2' p0,, -. "9 ....e m y 's and SMD candidate placement positively affects local PR vote outcomes. Additional qualitative data based on interviews with political actors in Russia and Ukraine demonstrate that political parties recognize contamination effects and develop strategies to take advantage of them. All of the evidence points to the emergence of multiparty competition in the PR and SMD components, as well as the entire mixed system, contradicting Duvergerian expectations. Copyright by Erik S. Herron 2000 For LeaMarie, my loving wife and patient editor By Its Vt .. 4. A‘ uFU‘JIIG-King W 355 of them by The if are 8.5 Last! UHI'I «C 9v r a . .lufil fl '3' are; ACKNOWLEDGMENTS By its very nature, a dissertation is a collective enterprise. Although only my name appears as author, I could not have completed this immense undertaking without the help and guidance of many people. While I cannot thank all of them by name without doubling the size of this volume, I want to give special thanks to a few special people. The first and most important person in the long list is my dear wife, LeaMarie Bistak Herron. Without Lea’s love, patience, sense of humor, innumerable sacrifices and skilled editing, this dissertation would not have been completed. My family and Lea’s family have also played a major role encouraging me as I worked both here and abroad. I especially want to acknowledge my parents, Thomas and Yvonne, and grandmother Ivy, who raised me to cherish education and pursue this final degree. I have also had many mentors at Michigan State who have skillfully guided me along the way. Brian Silver has always been ready to work with me on all of my projects and has spent countless hours helping me to hone my professional skills (his late night e-mails attest to his round-the-clock concern for my academic development). He has been a great mentor throughout my tenure as a graduate student. Dennis Patterson provided me with unquestioned support and counsel from the moment I arrived at MSU. He first introduced me to the issue that has become my dissertation. Mark Jones also encouraged my professional development and sparked my interest in electoral systems. Bill Reed provided invaluable assistance and helped me solve many methodological puzzles. vi Imus! e or he intal ve tie ideas m tr. Dee‘sped 0:: 5r: framertai :l Asa Fir;“.er F (I)- I must extend special thanks to Misa Nishikawa, my friend and co-author on the initial versions of our future “magnum opus” on mixed systems. Many of the ideas in the dissertation were hatched in conversations with Misa as we developed our c00perative and individual projects. Other scholars have been instrumental in honing my ideas and my approach to the dissertation, including Ada Finifter, Robert Lowry, and Tse-min Lin. The Department of Political Science support staff, Karen Battin, Rhonda Burns, lris Dunn and Elaine Eschtruth, also helped me in many ways. I also received quite a bit of assistance beyond East Lansing’s borders. Kathleen Bawn and Robert Moserk kindly offered their data to me, despite the fact that it would be used to question the assumptions of their own work. Moshe Haspel generously augmented the Russian data with material he acquired. Timothy Frye and Eric Browne offered substantial support for this project and continue to be advocates for my work. Outside of academe, Paul Harris at the New Zealand Electoral Commission responded to my requests for information about his country with blinding speed. J. Ray Kennedy at IFES in Washington put me in touch with the field offices in Russia and Ukraine that were instrumental in making my field work successful. It is also imperative to thank the American Councils for International Education under whose auspices I conducted field research in Ukraine and Russia. While I was in Kyiv, I had a large support network. Svetlana Napara provided me with a home and warm kasha every morning; I really mean every vii matting I re I'. .‘ 1 Wane. ind " Vac-nine and " at: Kr *' wSLja Sh; it???“ ‘ .0 .8] RC CEP” ‘ _: I A .9:- we 5.3.. at IFEt \ M» vb‘fix . W’v CSNC' M:%"-.' ,. diov morning. I received assistance from many other people and organizations in Ukraine, including: David Earl and the staff of IFES; Vladimir Pigenko, Ellie Valentine and the staff of the Parliamentary Development Project; Evhen Lapin and Kostya Shevchenko at Lab F 4; Thomas Garrett and Oksana Hasiuk at the International Republican Institute (IRI); Svetlana Kravtsova at the Ukrainian Central Electoral Commission; Olexander Lavrynovich and Igor Iosipenko. In Russia, Olga Gulikova gave me a home as well as syrniki and olady. I also received assistance from Bob Dahl, Christian Nadeau, Ksenia Tyurkova and the staff at IFES; Dr. Lee Patterson at IRI; Nikolai Petrov at the Carnegie Moscow Center; Viktor Sheynis; Vladimir and Natalya Ovcharenko and Valentin Mikhailov. While many names are not included in this list, their help is greatly appreciated and not forgotten. viii LIST OF TABL LIST OF FIGU LIST OF ABEF | | INTRODUCTIC L CHAPTER 1 INSTITUTION; ELECTORAL 5 Sector. 5 he I he I Che" ; An LITTLE; ; Instr. IUQKI Rese; Seal ;' COHCIus-O, i I I I I CHAPTER 2 WIEQRETICAL , [Ogle of c, . Party Site: 3 ESEargh L RESe.v Case 3 MPCP;' InveSf. ECho g TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES LIST OF FIGURES LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS INTRODUCTION CHAPTER 1 INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN, POLITICAL PARTIES AND MIXED ELECTORAL SYSTEMS Election Rules and Political Parties The Role of Political Parties The Development of Party Systems Challenges to Duverger’s Propositions An Introduction to Mixed Systems Institutional Variation in Mixed Systems Institutional Designers and Mixed Systems Research on Mixed Systems Seat Distribution in Mixed Systems Conclusions CHAPTER 2 THEORETICAL APPROACH AND RESEARCH DESIGN Logic of Contamination Effects Party Strategy Under Mixed Electoral Rules Research Design Research Hypotheses Case Selection and Data Sources Mechanical Effect Hypothesis Investment Effect Hypothesis Echo Effect Hypothesis Models 1a and 1b: Echo Effect Hypothesis with Controls for Popularity Model 2: Echo Effect Hypothesis with Controls for Regionalism Model 3: Echo Effect Hypothesis with Controls . for Independents Conclusions ix xi xiii xiv 13 15 15 20 25 31 31 36 46 51 55 58 61 65 71 71 73 74 76 79 83 85 86 87 CHAPTER 3 . THE MECHAI. Proportcr CONCLdSi: CHAPTER 4 THE lNVESTI.‘ Partlcapa; The E.“e:'. I Aftermate a Canclus :' CHAPTER 5 THE ECHO EFF Em E‘.‘e: Res; Res- ECDC “9: Echo E‘ie: C3723 defies CONCLLSQ-fi CONCLUSIONS GC‘Li-Afone St'a‘v‘igl: A: CCDCLUS'CQ Sump; Exit-3": COPS" AP"ENDICES AEC‘EndIX A "C=9hd;x B EP’JO’GRAPHY CHAPTER 3 THE MECHANICAL EFFECT 89 Proportionality Profiles 101 Conclusions 1 14 CHAPTER 4 THE INVESTMENT EFFECT 116 Participation in PR and SMD 119 The Effect of Resources on Participation 124 Alternate Explanations for SMD Placement 130 Conclusions 140 CHAPTER 5 THE ECHO EFFECT 142 Echo Effect Hypothesis, Models 1a and 1b 143 Results for Model 1a 143 Results for Model 1b 147 Echo Effect Hypothesis, Model 2 - The Effect of Regionalism 164 Echo Effect Hypothesis, Model 3 — The Effect of Independent Candidates 168 Conclusions 174 CHAPTER 6 CONCLUSIONS — PARTY STRATEGIES IN MIXED SYSTEMS 176 Go-lt—Alone Strategy — Ukraine’s Rukh Party 180 Strategic Alliance - Russia’s SP8 and Yabloko 182 Conclusions 185 Summary of Findings 185 Extensions of the Research 189 Concluding Remarks 192 APPENDICES 194 Appendix A - Data Sources 195 Appendix B - Additional Evidence for the Mechanical Effect 197 Appendix C — Additional Evidence for the Echo Effect 206 BIBLIOGRAPHY 215 Tat'e I, Ef‘eCf Mled Systems Tazie 8. Meet a are 7 Mew, '- V‘!“ L535 ‘2 SMD I L-‘uh. afl A, ~ ...a 13.; V»; T- I 3,719”. SMD F «3081028. U C ‘A e“: 4 7' e pS'ior, V \- . I ‘7 Pea. ; arr ‘A . 3:5 4: V Per‘I‘OFr \ =2:- 4A 3 penr". LIST OF TABLES Table 1: Effective Number of Parties for the SMD Component of Mixed Systems, SMD and PR Systems 4 Table 2: Electoral Rules of Selected Mixed Systems 37 Table 3: Seat Distribution in the Ukrainian Rada (1998) 52 Table 4: Distribution of Seats in Mid and West Wales Region 56 Table 5: Hypothetical Distribution of Candidates and Votes 81 Table 6: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Lithuania 1996 — Second Round) 92 Table 7: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Russia 1993) 95 Table 8: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Russia 1995) 96 Table 9: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Russia 1999) 98 Table 10: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Ukraine 1998) 100 Table 11: SMD Participation by Parties Registered in PR (Russia 1993, 1995 and 1999) 120 Table 12: SMD Participation by Parties Registered in PR (Lithuania 1996) 122 Table 13: SMD Participation by Parties Registered in PR (Ukraine 1998) 123 Table 14: Results for the Effect of Resources on SMD Placement 126 Table 15: Results for the Effects of Resources on SMD Placement (Fixed Effects Models) 129 Table 16: Performance of Small Parties (Russia 1999) 132 Table 17: Performance of KT R (Russia 1999) 133 Table 18: Performance of the LFU (Lithuania 1996) 134 Table 19: Performance of YL (Lithuania 1996) 135 xi T551920 Pe" late 21 Per" T352924. OLS Tate 23 OLS Ta:!e24 OLS T321325 OLS T. . :atle 3C H'y’CA. , U. m. -. n Mistat .Ion Ewe I ‘ ., 31. Hits" Jag/era. ~d,l0n O Table 20: Performance of WOM (Ukraine 1998) 137 Table 21: Performance of GDP (Ukraine 1998) 138 Table 22: OLS Results for Model 1a (Lithuania 1996) 144 Table 23: OLS Results for Model 1b (Russia 1995) 148 Table 24: OLS Results for Model 1b (Russia 1999) 151 Table 25: OLS Results for Models 1b and 2 (Ukraine 1998) 155 Table 26: OLS Results for Model 1b with Controls for Gubernatorial Affiliation (Russia 1999) 163 Table 27: Mean PR Vote and Number of Candidates by Region (Ukraine 1998) 166 Table 28: Number of Covert Partisans for Ukraine (1998) 170 Table 29: OLS Results for Model 3 (Ukraine 1998) 171 Table 30: Hypothetical Distribution of Votes and Seats with No Cooperation 1 77 Table 31: Hypothetical Distribution of Votes and Seats with Cooperation 178 Table 32: Nomination Patterns for SP8 and Yabloko in Moscow and St. Petersburg Districts (1999) 184 Table 33: OLS Results from Germany (1953) 208 Table 34: OLS Results from New Zealand (1996) 210 Table 35: OLS Results for Japan (1996) 212 Table 36: OLS Results for Japan (1996) with POPULARITY 213 xii Figure 1' A CI nge 2, Pro; Fzgs'e3 Pr: Figure 4 Pen Feces Prcp Figure 7: Prcpr "Th CCU/ , 7v . V- ,‘5 C300 LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1: A Classification of Mixed Systems Figure 2: Proportionality Profile for Lithuania (1996) Figure 3: Proportionality Profile for Russia (1993) Figure 4: Proportionality Profile for Russia (1995) Figure 5: Proportionality Profile for Russia (1999) Figure 6: Proportionality Profile for Ukraine (1998) Figure 7: Proportionality Profile for Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine Figure 8: Proportionality Profile for Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine with 95% Confidence Intervals Figure 9: Proportionality Profile for Armenia Figure 10: Proportionality Profile for Japan Figure 11: Proportionality Profile for New Zealand Figure 12: Proportionality Profile for Scotland Figure 13: Proportionality Profile for Wales Figure 14: Proportionality Profile for All Countries xiii 49 104 107 108 109 110 112 113 198 199 201 202 203 205 LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS FSU Former Soviet Union PR Proportional Representation SMD Single Member District Political Parties in Germany BP Bavarian Party CDU Christian Democratic Union DP Deutsche Party FDP Free Democratic Party SPD Social Democratic Party 2 Zentrum Political Parties in Japan DPJ Democratic Party of Japan LDP Liberal Democratic Party NF P New Frontier Party NHP New Harbinger Party SDPJ Social Democratic Party of Japan Shin. Shinshakaito Political Parties in Lithuania CDU Christian Democratic Union Econ Lithuanian Party of the Economy LCU Lithuanian Center Union LLU Lithuanian Liberal Union LNU Lithuanian National Union LL Party of Life’s Logic Peasants Lithuanian Peasants’ Party Poles Alliance Lithuanian Poles’ Electoral Alliance Pol. Prisoners Lithuanian Union of Political Prisoners and Deportees Socialists Lithuanian Socialist Party Women New DemocracyNVomen’s Party YL Lithuanian National Party “Young Lithuania” Political Parties in New Zealand CC Christian Coalition MS McGillicuddy Serious Party PG Progressive Greens UNZ United New Zealand xiv Political Parties in Russia AN-SF Bloc of Andrey Nikolayev and Svyatoslav Fyodorov APR Agrarian Party of Russia DN Spiritual Heritage DVR Democratic Choice of Russia KPRF Communist Party of the Russian Federation KRO Congress of Russian Communities KTR Communists — Workers of Russia — for the Soviet Union LDPR Liberal Democratic Party of Russia NDR Our Home is Russia OVR Fatherland — All Russia RSP Russian Socialist Party Rybkin Bloc of Ivan Rybkin SPS Union of Right Forces Political Parties in Ukraine APU Agrarian Party of Ukraine Bloc Dem Bloc of Democratic Parties CDP Christian Democratic Party KPU Communist Party of Ukraine Nat F National Front NDP People’s Democratic Party PSP Progressive Socialist Party RAZOM Party of Rights and Liberal Party R&O Reform and Order S&P Bloc Bloc of Socialists and Peasants SDPU Social Democratic Party (United) UNA Ukrainian National Assembly Political Parties in Wales Con Conservative Party Green Green Party Ind. Turner Independent Turner Lab Labour Party LD Liberal Democrat party NLP Natural Law Party PC Plaid Cymru SocLab Socialist Labour Party XV DIME-'96 the two- Duvergé balls- 4 Dave"; he adv logettef Instead (Sanon Fordece testes that er. recesses Re: I"!!! me upon 2' 1?th .c. dc not die INTRODUCTION Duverger’s Law: “[t]he simple-majority single-ballot system...favors the two-party system" (Duverger 1954, 217) Duverger’s Hypothesis: “[tjhe simple-majority system with second ballot and proportional representation favors multipartyism” (Duverger 1954, 239). The advocates of plurality-PR hybrids believe that they are bringing together the best of two worlds; but they are likely to obtain, instead, a bastard-producing hybrid which combines their defects (Sartori 1997a, 75). For decades, political scientists have struggled to uncover universal theories that explain the behavior of individuals and groups involved in political processes. Rather than developing research programs that encompass and improve upon previous analyses,1 scholars often pursue independent agendas that do not directly contribute to the construction of general theories of politics. This tendency is particularly prevalent in comparative politics where schools of thought historically have been tied to researchers’ ideological preferences and theories are transitory (Geddes 1991 ). There is at least one exception to this process. Riker (1982) indicates that the study of political party systems and the interaction between institutions and parties has followed a “Lakatosian” path. Since Maurice Duverger formalized his theories about the relationship between institutional rules and the number of political parties, the study of party systems has moved forward by incorporating earlier scholarship. While some critics 1 Imre Lakatos (1978) provides the seminal definition of a scientific research program. suggest that :r 6513;831:002 ” rcie In shaprr; Duverge | crgmal some: I e‘ecrve In ex; | 1959. Feeders- | mncepts to ve' er: Sevetsora Va'etzueia 132- Ketashima 19; .. ”a“ v. y ~ as of Duve: ‘I. ”rein {‘ r- 5 "CI has. suggest that institutions have little impact on the development of partisan competition,2 most political scientists accept the idea that institutions play some role in shaping the party system. Duverger‘s work has spawned many efforts to refine and expand his original concepts. Scholars have studied how Duverger’s Propositions are effective in explaining party systems (Palfrey 1989; Taagepera and Shugart 1989; Feddersen, Sened and Wright 1990; Fey 1997) and have applied the concepts to various countries (Lijphart 1984, 1994; Reed 1990, 1999; Ordeshook and Shvetsova 1994; Wada 1995; Kawato 1996; Gebethner 1996; Siavelis and Valenzuela 1996; Neto and Cox 1997; Chhibber and Kollman 1997; Cox 1997; Kabashima 1998; Jones 1999; Chhibber and Norfuddin 2000). Although the effects of Duverger’s Law and Hypothesis have been studied in various institutional and cultural environments, the expansion of new electoral institutions creates the opportunity to extend Duverger’s Propositions beyond traditional settings. I argue that mixed electoral systems - those with both proportional representation (PR) and single-member district (SMD) components - present strategic incentives to candidates and parties that differ from those found in independent PR or SMD systems with plurality rules. These incentives should influence the development of the party system in ways not addressed by Duverger. This research challenges the extension of Duverger’s Propositions, 2 Epstein (1980) has criticized institutional approaches to the study of party system development. 2 that l w": I call ' bath ‘PPC'EiICE Hill I: ivvr I Schoia' systems miles I fetter: lhcsl o’esgrters =th I | fiaIe erred, Tr | C0920. have 58' 8933033 STOCE VOTE 0,; liter these n; . 53'3” SI‘Stem E that I will call “Duvergerian expectations,” to hybrid systems and is important for both theoretical and practical reasons.3 Scholarly research that has analyzed the two components of mixed systems independently may be invalid if strategic incentives in mixed systems differ from those in standard PR and SMD systems. In addition, institutional designers who selected mixed systems under Duvergerian expectations may have erred. The failure of mixed systems to produce the predicted outcomes could have serious implications for the population’s trust in parliament and the electoral process.4 Vote outcomes in mixed systems suggest that party systems emerging under these rules diverge from Duvergerian expectations. The SMD portion of the mixed system does not seem to have the anticipated reductive effect on the party system. By comparing the effective number of parties in the SMD component of mixed systems to the effective number of parties found in PR and SMD systems, we see that the mixed system’s SMD portion generally exceeds the effective number of parties in standard SMD systems (see Table 1).5 3 The dissertation thus challenges later scholars' interpretations of Duverger's work rather than Duverger’s own conclusions. I use the term “Duvergerian expectations” to denote interpretations of Duverger’s work and not Duverger’s own Propositions. Specifically, Duvergerian expectations refer to the assumption that PR and SMD components of mixed systems are independent and that Duverger's Propositions should thus apply to each part separately. I will use Duverger’s Propositions when specifically referring to Duverger’s own work. Ukrainian voters expressed their dissatisfaction with parliament’s inability to govern in a referendum conducted on April 16, 2000. They authorized the president to redesign the legislative branch in part due to fragmentation within the legislature that undermined its ability to Qovem. This fragmentation is due, in part, to the mixed electoral rules used to elect parliamentary deputies. The effective number of parties is calculated using the Laakso-Taagepera index which is: / 2 where p is the proportion of votes received by the party in the district. For Armenia, p, Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine, I calculate the effective number of parties by taking the mean of each district's effective number of parties in order to account for independent candidates. Table 1: E‘ 8110 Systems I ‘r Terrey 1933-: U 8. House 19' N-C’way 1882. ‘|' US Secate 1? SCSI). Africa 132‘ Sieden 1887: New Zealand ‘ Ll"- :ee‘ KINGS" Canada 19:136. De'rark 193:- late 1951-71 Table 1: Effective Number of Parties for the SMD Component of Mixed Systems, SMD and PR Systems6 SMD Systems # PR Systems # Mixed Systems # Turkey 1950-57 2.1 Belgium 1848-94 2.1 Scotland 1999 3.8 US. House 1910-70 2.1 Austria 1923-70 2.4 Wales 1999 3.8 Norway 1882-1903 2.2 Austria 1971 -79 2.4 Japan 1996 3.9 US. Senate 1912-70 2.2 Greece 1928,33,35,52 2.6 New Zealand 1996 4.1 South Africa 1958-74 2.3 Australia 1919-80 2.9 Armenia 1999 4.2 Sweden 1887-1905 2.3 Greece 1951, 56-77 3.0 Russia 1999 4.6 New Zealand 1946-84 2.4 Ireland 1923-77 3.1 Russia 1993 4.7 United Kingdom 1900-77 2.5 Turkey 1961-77 3.1 Lithuania 1996 5.6 Canada 1949-80 3.1 Japan 1928-80 3.3 Russia 1995 5.9 Denmark 1901 -1 3 3.8 Sweden 1952-68 3.4 Ukraine 1998 6.0 India 1951-71 4.3 Belgium 1919-77 3.5 Italy 1946-76 3.5 Luxembourg 1919-79 3.5 Sweden 1908-49 3.5 Sweden 1970-76 3.5 Iceland 1959-74 3.7 Norway 1930-49 3.8 Norway 1953-77 3.8 Venezuela 1947-73 4.0 France 1945-46 4.5 Israel 1959-77 4.5 Greece 4.8 1926,32,36,46,50 Netherlands 1937-52 5.1 Switzerland 1919-75 5.3 Finland 1906-83 5.4 Netherlands 1937-52 5.4 Netherlands 1918-33 5.8 Germany 1920-33 6.0 Estonia 1919-32 6.6 Mean 2.7 Mean 3.9 Mean 4.7 findard Deviation 0.7 Standard Deviation 1.2 Standard Deviation 0.9 6 The designation “all“ in columns 2, 4 and 6 refers to the effective number of elective parties. Sources: Asahi Senkyo Taikan; BBC; Central Electoral Commission of Armenia; Central Electoral C0mmission of the Russian Federation; Central Electoral Commission of Ukraine; Electoral Commission of Lithuania; Taagepera and Shugart (1989). 4 l'Ihle Dev/ET; wmpettiiOI‘l lr prs-duced a t. he 'pure" Sl.’ xntrast. the r: Systems iS 5.2 alerege hum: ”ended more he Slit com I T) sates In seit-r The PR hargrrta! partze sari es Comps; Tasy small {,3 L" 39 Omar my While Duverger’s Law indicates that SMD systems should produce two-party competition in districts over time, the SMD component of mixed systems has produced a higher number of effective parties than “pure” SMD systems. Among the “pure” SMD systems, the mean number of effective parties is 2.7. By contrast, the mean number of effective parties among post-communist mixed systems is 5.2. If we include mixed systems outside the former Soviet Union, the average number of effective parties is 4.7. While the sample size is too small to conduct more rigorous statistical analysis of all cases, the number of parties in the SMD component of mixed systems tends to exceed the effective number of parties in self-contained SMD systems. The PR threshold in mixed systems also does not seem to restrict marginal parties from participating in elections. In Russia’s 1995 elections, 43 parties competed in the PR section. This number was reduced to 26 in 1999, but many small parties are active in both PR and SMD. While the number of parties in the other mixed systems analyzed has not exceeded Russia’s 1995 contingent, a substantial contingent of both competitive and marginal parties have committed to electoral competition. The large number of parties in many mixed systems could be due, in part, to the newness of the electoral systems; not enough time has passed for the “psychological effect” to reduce the size of party competition.7 There is another possibility as well. Perhaps the combination of PR and SMD rules undermines the properties that produce party systems based on Duvergerian expectations. If mixed systems present political actors with different incentives, political parties and candidate QTYI’ITOI'ImenI Is :ased on a: ‘cnahon of pg 9933'), The ; ETCOL'ages CC ' and voters to r‘ k. Pl" I'rVTC'Ie .m'r‘t-v- 1.1“" L I” .ETESIS and candidates should adopt different strategies to be successful In this environment. How do optimal strategies differ in PR, SMD and mixed systems? In a PR system, small parties have a greater potential for gaining seats in the legislature if the threshold for representation is low. Because seat allocation is based on aggregate performance, a party does not need to win a majority or plurality of votes in any local electoral district to gain legislative representation. This encourages small parties to participate in elections and facilitates the formation of parties based around specific concerns (i.e., regions, ethnicity, gender). The ability of small parties to gain access to the legislature further encourages contributors to support these parties, candidates to align with them, and voters to cast their ballots for them. For these reasons, PR systems tend to promote multipartism and allow political parties to form around more specific interests. In addition, PR generally encourages greater party discipline. Although open-list PR has been shown to discourage compliance with party norms (Shugart 1994; Ames 1995a, 1995b), closed-list PR is more common.8 In closed-list PR, the party itself controls the construction of the party list.9 Candidates who have shown party loyalty are more likely to gain access to the list and to obtain a higher rank. Failure to follow the expectations of national- level leaders can lead to a low rank or exclusion from the list. In a PR system, :3 I address the psychological effect in detail in Chapter 1. Among the mixed systems under analysis in the dissertation, only Lithuania uses open-list PR. Seat allocation within a PR system is determined, in part, by the party list. After the number of seats that a party is to receive is determined by application of the electoral formula, seats are assigned based on the list. A party rank-orders its candidates from first to the end of the list. If a party receives fifteen seats, for example, candidates ranked one through fifteen would receive seats in parliament. Seat allocation will be addressed in greater detail in Chapter 2. 6 exclusion fror from gamg : control over c natonaffy-fc-ct manS en a mapréty le accsrhpl sh 'eccgnrze that cistrid. they a Scarces o‘ “L III,,' » 'eccgnzzed as Catheters lf‘, exclusion from the list or a very low ranking effectively eliminates the candidate from gaining access to the legislature. If a party exerts a greater degree of control over candidates, it converts local concerns and pork barrel politics to a nationally-focused agenda. In an SMD system, by contrast, the best way to gain representation is to win a majority of the votes in a single electoral district. The most efficient manner to accomplish this task is to form local electoral alliances. When voters recognize that a candidate or party will not finish among the top two in the district, they are more likely to throw their support behind a potential winner. Sources of financial support will also erode over time if the party is not recognized as a legitimate local contender. Through this process, the number of competitors in SMD races should pare down to two. This process does not guarantee two major parties competing nationally. Rather, party competition will eventually approach two effective candidates in any district. Party aggregation at the national level is a separate concern. Nevertheless, the strategic incentives provided to parties in an SMD system generally favor larger political parties and undermine small alliances. While larger electoral blocs are generally more successful in SMD systems, the degree of party loyalty is also lower. Candidates strive to satisfy the needs of local constituencies to win votes in the local race because each candidate must win his or her own district to gain representation. Thus, the effectiveness of the party at the national-level is less relevant for local performance. Policy positions that stray from official platforms are thus more common In 87 oo..ntry like t' It systems W with the party geoerafly pres LID systems The err new and esta: o7 PR and SI.’ Tee Integrate "w‘fiidSng 5:3" ‘09 meed SVSf~ B5“ Ia I “Ci-Tar strate- I COME." Si'afegrc anen. I“. e Coma?) ~ InailOr‘ ‘ “an-es. M E‘s-4 ”Mal TUE-s common in SMD systems than in PR systems. This is particularly true in a country like the United States, where ballot access is determined by primaries. In systems where ballot access is determined by the party, the degree of discord with the party platform should be less measurable. Nevertheless, parties generally present a more cohesive platform and vision in PR systems than in SMD systems. The emergence of mixed electoral systems as a popular choice for both new and established democracies raises a new question: Does the combination of PR and SMD into a single election affect the strategies of political parties? The integration of electoral rules with contradictory incentives may send confusing signals to political parties. Alternatively, parties could recognize that the mixed system provides its own unique set of incentives and that certain electoral strategies are more effective in this environment. I contend that the latter approach is correct. Moreover, I will show that the strategic incentives in mixed systems are rooted in contamination effects. Contamination is the interaction between PR and SMD components of mixed systems that underlies the decision-making of voters, contributors, candidates and parties. Mixed systems are not a combination of two independent sets of electoral rules. Rather, each component affects the other. The decisions of political actors necessarily take the whole system into account. While existing scholarship suggests that political actors compartmentalize the PR and SMD sections, I will provide strong evidence of interaction. T Ie e» tentative y es Ir an an ‘ys s 2030). i eat . meme 'llS : xIntaT’TlT 3M3" tromtwo m" control it ' SC” Tr s d <- twitt: de‘ 3 fr: he come her from thos . to; roe-chants I e“ heChar‘I .c IL e“ tc carfICIp rte l' The sec “knit. .cy to pg 115,; "A” we ,;C:pate m I: WI: ‘Dete In tr I}. 9:293 W H I5 Ill :39 The existence of contamination effects in mixed systems has been tentatively established. I will expand upon the preliminary conclusions produced in an analysis of Japanese and Russian election data (Herron and Nishikawa 2000). That work demonstrated the existence of contamination across the components of the mixed system. While the evidence is convincing, contamination is characterized as a single effect and the tests are limited to data from two countries that have similar mixed systems. The research also fails to control for some potential rival explanations. This dissertation further develops the theoretical argument and evaluates it with data from additional mixed systems. I assess three hypotheses to support the contention that mixed systems produce a set of strategic incentives that differ from those found in PR and SMD systems. The first hypothesis is that the mechanical effect in mixed systems is more forgiving to marginal parties than the mechanical effect in SMD systems. If this is true, small parties should continue to participate in elections over time. The second hypothesis builds off the first. Given that small parties are likely to participate in elections, how will they participate? While parties could participate in PR or SMD alone, the second hypothesis suggests that parties will participate in the whole mixed system, contingent upon resources. That is, parties will attempt to gain seats in both the PR and SMD sections of the mixed system. The final hypothesis evaluates whether or not a party’s placement of candidates in SMD affects performance in PR. lf candidate placement affects PR vote out: SMD. Pl! titre the PR 2 no S Dorerge 'san -: T re d: LIIE'BiJTE on : Part-es a Id pa ESP-733’ es 1: SISIQT’IS Is dag I. . “Gal/10p . . \ , __ — — — — PR vote outcomes, parties will be further encouraged to place candidates in SMD. All three hypotheses support the emergence of multiparty competition in the PR and SMD components and in the whole system, contradicting Duvergerian expectations. The dissertation will be structured as follows. Chapter 1 reviews the literature on party system development. In this chapter, I address why political parties and party systems are important and specifically why institutional approaches to party system development are the most fruitful. The chapter also discusses mixed systems by providing a detailed description of existing mixed systems, variation among the electoral rules within these systems, and how seats are allocated in different types of mixed systems. Chapter Two addresses the theoretical approach of the dissertation. I provide a more formal definition of contamination and demonstrate the problems of ignoring its existence. I also emphasize the failure of the existing literature to adequately address mixed systems. Although much of the literature on mixed systems is descriptive, some scholarly work uses mixed systems to test the behavior of voters, political elites and parties. The dominant trend in this literature is to ignore contamination effects, undermining our confidence in the authors’ conclusions. I also discuss the research design in Chapter Two. I will use district-level election data to evaluate various forms of contamination. The analysis focuses on data from Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine, although data from Armenia, Germany, Japan, New Zealand, Scotland and Wales are used to augment the 10 anafysls anC lelso prowde In Che Using a meat demonstrate : I’vestrnem E‘- 3')d ordInary A, .- .. eedoral pa In Char .Lamlna‘ron ' We 01 ch dCSS Contra: analysis and extend it beyond post-communist mixed systems.10 In this chapter, I also provide information on the variables used in the analysis and their coding. In Chapter Three, I analyze the mechanical effect in mixed systems. Using a measure of disproportionality as well as a scatterplot smoother, l demonstrate that the mechanical effect in mixed systems is more forgiving to small parties than the mechanical effect in SMD systems (as defined by Taagepera and Shugart 1989). In Chapter Four, I address the first form of contamination, which I label the Investment Effect. I employ descriptive statistics of party nomination patterns and ordinary least squares (OLS) analysis to show that parties tend to participate in both components of the mixed system and that their resources affect the level of electoral participation. In Chapter Five, l demonstrate the existence of another element of contamination, which I call the Echo Effect. OLS analysis shows that the placement of candidates in SMD affects the vote outcomes for parties in PR. This type of contamination should encourage parties to participate in many SMD races, contingent upon resources and the electoral environment. In Chapter 6, I present qualitative evidence from research in Russia and Ukraine that supports the existence of contamination effects. Not only do these effects manifest themselves in quantitative analysis, but they are explicitly understood by political actors in the region. International organizations have advised parties to take advantage of the effects and some political parties have ‘0 These tests are included in the appendices. 11 C . ‘ . led 8 VV\ ll1 8 qual’ Iati‘ formed electoral strategies with contamination effects in mind. After presenting the qualitative evidence, I summarize the findings and present conclusions. 12 INSTITUT were faced 'A .nsttstlonal r- :Q‘ hi I Lusan‘sne.d C 534911 to Tesf IDSIliqf fifties Of the n, LC 953” Other 2 Chapter 1 INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN, POLITICAL PARTIES AND MIXED ELECTORAL SYSTEMS The final decade of the twentieth century witnessed an increased interest in institutional design and its role in determining the environment for competitive politics. Former communist regimes, emerging from authoritarian, one-party rule, were faced with inventing institutions in a new era of independence. Interest in institutional tinkering was not limited to newly independent states, however. Established democracies also reevaluated the efficacy of their institutions and sought to restructure some of them. Institutions, the array of formal and informal arrangements that define the “rules of the game” in politics, establish how different elements of the state relate to each other and how individuals attain positions of authority (North 1990). They determine, in part, who is in a position to make policy, what views are represented at the highest levels of government, and what mechanisms are used to resolve conflicts in society. Because institutions can exert such an important influence on the outcome of political disputes, decisions to select or alter institutions are not taken lightly. Constitutional engineers face an almost unlimited combination of choices that can lead to stable democratic governance: a presidential or parliamentary system; a unitary or federal state; a centralized or decentralized state authority; a unicameral or bicameral parliament; and a variety of electoral rules for local, 13 regsonal and they are not Afiert control In Ea: forced to take representatrv governments. compromise t existing syste Corsetrr-g Cor Deepne i . .. =EcSIP‘ we Instrtu 5‘3 primary mg aSSDClated Wli System Is not 9 5., l regional and national offices. Institutional choices may seem wide in theory, but they are not unlimited in practice. After the initial period of euphoria following the ouster of Communist Party control in Eastern Europe and the post-Soviet region, institutional designers were forced to take into account the competing demands of the victorious opposition, representatives of the failed regime, international organizations and foreign governments. Institutional changes in established democracies also required compromise between the advocates of reform and those who benefited from the existing system. The development of new institutions is based on the desires of competing constituencies (Bawn 1993; Remington and Smith 1996). Despite these constraints, institutional designers have a large menu of feasible institutional structures. To further complicate the environment, each of the primary institutional choices mentioned above has lower-level options associated with it. For instance, the choice of a presidential or parliamentary system is not dichotomous; a collection of secondary, tertiary and other choices must be made to define the rules of the new political system. The powers of the president vis-a-vis other institutions and political actors must be established. Decisions must be made about the term of office, the electoral formula, timing of the election relative to other elections, and how candidates will be selected. Each of these choices affects the development of political competition and each institutional choice affects the others. The collection of institutions that define the political system is influential because it has a “genetic code that programs the kinds of bureaucracies, 14 leadersh:p ST ultimately me Important I L ,- L r‘ s‘ I IRSEILLIIOT‘IaI C leadership structures, personnel arrangements, and other properties that will ultimately make up its government” (Moe and Caldwell 1994, 192). Countries rarely change their institutions dramatically, so the initial choice at every level is important (Lijphart 1984; Shugart and Carey 1992; Jones 1995).11 Few institutional choices doom democracy to failure, but some are more conducive to democratic survival than others (Jones 1995). Although the total effect of each choice cannot be completely understood independently, it is useful to analyze the direct effects of each selection on political competition. Election Rules and Political Parties The selection of election rules for the legislature may seem to be a relatively minor issue in the context of institutional design, but electoral institutions play a critical role in structuring partisan competition. By establishing the rules for political contests, electoral systems directly affect the strategic behavior of political elites and voters. While sociological and historical factors can also influence how competition develops, political variables are primary determinants of the party system. The Role of Political Parties Political parties are organizations that not only are able to participate in elections but choose to do so (Sartori 1976; Mainwaring and Scully 1995). Despite pessimistic interpretations of the utility of political parties and “ When established democracies change their institutional rules, the changes are usually limited in scape and are more difficult to implement. 15 suggestion in both est; Sch: democrat: he org ns l ilat Pa'izes cadre of 92:: Vu’emer 1:...5 mil-lax p05 modernzzatll the tomes Cl suggestions that they are declining in importance, parties have critical functions in both established and new democratic states.12 Scholars disagree about the most important contributions of parties to democratic political life. Views of party functions are often linked to beliefs about the origins of parties. Political scientists in the modernization school have argued that parties emerged when public policy could no longer be made by a small cadre of elites who were unconcerned with public opinion (LaPalombara and Weiner 1966). The advent of mass suffrage, combined with the increasingly complex post-Industrial Revolution world, required parties. Like much of the modernization literature, however, this analysis emphasizes a vague notion of the forces of history as the causal mechanism in the formation of parties. The role of political actors is subsumed under the sweeping power of social and historical change. Other scholars focus on suffrage as a key element in the development of parties. Parties link society and the political world by mediating society’s cleavages. in this argument, the forum of conflict was longitudinally consistent in Western democracies during the early twentieth century. The cleavages of the 19605 were virtually identical to those of forty years earlier (Lipset and Rokkan 1967). Thus, the substance of partisan competition was consistent. Worldwide economic and cultural change in the 19608 challenged this notion of continuity, however. The development of competitive party systems outside Western '2 Many scholars have suggested that the importance of political parties has declined. Their salience in the United States (Nie, Verba and Petrocik1976; Wattenberg 1990) and in other countries has been questioned in the face of an increasingly disenchanted and independent electorate (Dalton, Flanagan and Beck 1984). 16 Europe and power of the Defin ccrtme {0 ; Europe and North America also undermined the external validity and explanatory power of the argument. Definitions of parties as linkage structures that emerged due to suffrage continue to permeate the literature. Epstein (1980) states that parties “were needed to provide clarity and continuity for an enlarged public.” He emphasizes social factors in the development of party systems and indicates that “the different historical origin of parties helps to explain the differences in their organizational type” (ibid., 99). Prior to mass suffrage, there was little need to provide labels to help identify candidates’ positions on the issues. However, after the extension of suffrage, new, relatively uneducated voters required a simple means to distinguish among competitors. Parties emerged to provide these cues to the public. Once again, parties are viewed as a historic necessity rather than as a product of ambitious political actors. Epstein explicitly rejects institutional rules as an explanation for party system development, preferring to explain party systems by their proximity to civil service reforms and their relationship to social, cultural and geographic cleavages. While he acknowledges that some institutions may affect party systems (notably federalism and the parliamentary/presidential dichotomy), Epstein denies the influence of electoral laws and rejects the basic tenets of Duverger’s Propositions. In contrast to scholars who emphasize social forces in the establishment of political parties, researchers in the rational choice tradition argue that parties 17 emerged as Parties are "' politicians V 30:3:r problems in 1934), in at". for citizens i pa'ticuiarly tr between cam spend gathe' who are affil: iBchnrton t.‘ atiiffy to gar Candidates 1‘ W :t'mr 53’ iEduCing t 54159011 Of the acrcss time C emerged as tools for astute political actors to gain office and make policy. Parties are not formed as a required step in political evolution, but because politicians view them as useful for their own purposes: election and governance. According to this argument, parties emerged to address collective action problems in election campaigns and in the legislature (Schlesinger 1991; Aldrich 1994). In an election, political actors must overcome the perceived disincentives for citizens to vote. Parties can mobilize citizens by reducing the costs of voting, particularly those associated with collecting information. By providing a link between candidates and an ideological label, parties reduce the time voters must spend gathering data to make an informed decision about voting. Candidates who are affiliated with parties also accrue benefits because of the instant recognition the party label provides.13 Moreover, as a party demonstrates its ability to gain office and make policy, it transfers credibility to affiliated candidates.14 Within legislative assemblies, parties allow political actors to make policy by reducing uncertainty. In the absence of parties, majorities may form in support of individual policies, but these coalitions are not likely to be consistent across time or issue. Political parties in the legislature provide consistency and certainty, allowing representatives to achieve their preferred policy ends more often than in the absence of these coalitions (Shepsle 1986). Because parties _ 13 The notion of parties as labels is rooted in the work of Downs (1957). This relationship has been further explored by Kiewiet and McCubbins (1991), Cox and McCubbins (1993), Aldrich 1995) and others as an element in electoral and legislative behavior. Conversely, as a party shows that it is incapable of winning office or providing a platform responsive to the interests of the electorate, its credibility will decline. This will lead to abandonment by voters, candidates and sources of financial support. See Aldrich's (1994) 18 generate 515 the benefits membersh? I ”per whesaea owever. if; sebsumed L.’ problems V. tins analysgs gcrem. Thus sectoral proé generate stability and consistency, ambitious politicians are likely to form them if the benefits of joining a party are greater than any costs associated with membership. 1 If parties emerge as a response to changes in social structures and to mediate political conflict, their primary functions are to provide citizens with a link to the state and to information about the ideological beliefs of candidates. However, if parties are tools for political actors, their communication functions are subsumed under their role as instruments in overcoming collective action problems. While parties may have multiple functions, the assumption underlying this analysis is that a party’s main role is to help politicians win elections and govern. Thus, a political organization is not a party unless it participates in the electoral process.15 Candidates sometimes seek office without a party affiliation. This is particularly true in countries with inchoate party systems. In some new democracies, the costs of the party label may outweigh the benefits, prompting candidates to participate as independents (Smyth 1997; Moser 1999b). In many cases, however, institutional rules within the legislature encourage independents to join parties once they gain seats in parliament. Access to committee assignments and other perquisites are generally controlled by parties; unaffiliated discussion of the decline of the Whig Party and emergence of the Republican Party in the United States for an example of this process. ‘5 In many mixed systems, a distinction is drawn between parties that participate in elections and those that emerge in the legislature. Parties that are in the legislature are labeled 'frakstii" or factions in Russia and Ukraine. Thus, they are not parties by definition - only groups that participate in the electoral process are called parties. 19 legzsiatzve p from comp-e? l The Develo, Wher E‘Clher, The $5er 19"; . ,U w QC“; emanCe legislators are handicapped in the policy-making process."3 While political actors may choose to participate as independents in the election, pressures during the legislative period should discourage large numbers of independent candidates from competing in the long-run. The Development of Party Systems Wherever political parties emerge, they cooperate and compete with one another. The “system of interactions resulting from inter-party competition” (Sartori 1976, 44) constitutes the party system. Just as the development of individual parties responds to the institutional features of the electoral and governance systems, so too does the party system. Political scientists have developed two general measures to define party systems: the number of parties in the system and their ideological distance. Initial forays into the classification of party systems focused on the number of parties (Duverger 1954). Scholars subsequently expanded the analysis to the competitive structure (Dahl 1966), the number and relative size of parties (Blondel 1968), the number of parties and majority formation (Rokkan 1968) and the number and ideological distance between parties (Sartori 1976). While measures of party systems have varied, the number of parties in a system has consistently played a central role. The number of parties in a system is critical in determining who has power. Giovanni Sartori (1976, 120) indicates that “it does matter how many are ‘6 Rules encouraging deputies to join parliamentary parties exist in Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine (Haspel, Remington and Smith 1998; Clark, Holscher and Hyland 1999; D’Anieri 2000). 20 the partres roughly. an power is ire; analyzing tr can undersfs and how mav ccndrtrons cr Maurlr have their 0.. Ml‘. linked e, the parties. For one thing, the number of parties immediately indicates, albeit roughly, an important feature of the political system: the extent to which political power is fragmented or non-fragmented, dispersed or concentrated.” By analyzing the effects of institutions on the development of the party system, we can understand how parties interact with one another, how power is distributed, and how many and what types of political organizations thrive under the specific conditions created by the country’s institutions. Maurice Duverger formalized the direct link between electoral institutions and the number of parties in the system. Duverger’s Propositions, however, have their origins in the work of other scholars. As early as 1867, John Stuart Mill linked electoral rules and the party system. Mill suggested that adoption of proportional representation in Great Britain would undermine the two-party system. Two years later, Henry Droop posited that two-party competition would result from the use of a plurality rule for seat distribution in SMD races." These conclusions were based on logic rather than empirical evidence. Nevertheless, they show that a close connection between electoral rules and party systems was recognized far earlier than Duverger’s more formal elaboration of his Propositions. Early scholars who supported the idea that electoral rules affect the nature of partisan competition presaged a logic that is implicit in formal analyses developed by modern political scientists. Plurality rules tend to lead to two-party competition because the only way to be certain of victory in an SMD race is to receive the majority of the votes in a district. When more than two candidates 21 compete. tr reduced. T and candid; :ndwidual p; hcwerer, tr»: achzeve 11161 0'? predzction Duverl laws 10 pro: 'ep’esemazzz ”33W Sir‘: compete, the likelihood that one candidate will garner a majority is substantially reduced. This creates uncertainty about the outcome among voters, contributors and candidates. If ambitious politicians group themselves into coalitions, however, they can increase their probability of winning a majority. The notion of individual politicians, weighing costs and benefits, and choosing cooperation to achieve their ends is the basis of the rational choice approach and is at the heart of predictions based on Duverger’s Propositions. Duverger’s Law18 and Hypothesis assert that a plurality ballot system tends to produce a two-party system at the district level and proportional representation leads to multipartism. Duverger’s Law states that “[t]he simple- majority single-ballot system...favors the two-party system” (Duverger 1954, 217) and Duverger’s Hypothesis indicates that “[t]he simple-majority system with second ballot and proportional representation favors multipartyism” (Duverger 1954, 239). Thus, Duverger’s Law and Hypothesis address the major forms of electoral rules used at the time and their implications for party system development. The ballot systems’ effects take two forms. The mechanical effect is the filtering of votes into legislative seats, that is, how votes are counted and accumulated in order to allocate seats. Generally, small parties in an SMD system with plurality rules are under-represented; they receive some degree of support in the electorate, but win a plurality in few, if any, districts. Unless a marginal party has a strong regional following and is thereby competitive in one ‘7 See Riker 1982 and Cox 1997 for a discussion of the origins of Duverger’s Propositions. 22 or a handft praportrona systems 95* lnaF afid distnou: national leve relatively hog 599,30” in CS ’EQ-Séture 531839 18p! marginal p0; eel-3mm Of 9337533th V J‘s-fit USlh 9 SMD \ or a handful of districts, it is unlikely to receive seats in parliament that are proportionate to its support in the electorate. The mechanical effect in these systems can be described as punishing to small parties. In a PR system, smaller parties are more likely to be represented, although the degree of proportionality depends on the rules used to count votes and distribute seats. A small party needs only to overcome the threshold at the national level to win a place in parliament.19 This can be achieved through relatively homogenous support throughout the country or through concentrated support in certain regions that are large enough to push the party into the legislature. A party need not win a plurality of the vote in a specific region to achieve representation. The mechanical effect in PR is thus less punishing to marginal political parties because they are more likely to receive a proportionate allocation of seats under this system than under SMD. The mechanical effect interacts with the psychological effect. By translating voter preferences into actual representation, the mechanical effect produces the cues that parties use to decide whether or not to participate in subsequent elections. The psychological effect suggests that voters in countries using SMD with plurality rules will fail to support small parties in general because they do not want to waste their votes. That is, voters will behave strategically.20 '8 Technically, Duverger never called Duverger's Law a law. He simply stated that it "approaches most nearly...to a true sociological law.” '9 In some cases, the distribution of seats in PR is aggregated at a regional level. In this case, a plurality is also unnecessary - the party must simply overcome the threshold to receive seats within the regional district. This facilitates representation for small parties with a regional focus by increasing the likelihood that they will overcome the local threshold. 2° If a voter behaves strategically, she will not choose the most preferred candidate if that candidate is unlikely to finish among the top two in an SMD race. Rather, the voter will select between the most competitive candidates. The alternative is to vote sincerely and choose the 23 lndwrduals —'_— from non-CC assoczate tr win seats, reseurces a they are like two Competil aafidiclates a 5”laid- ever sure“) We to . I' 0 ”Users are l RM? - "’ 91" r. ” Germany, Italy, New Zealand, Scotland, Tunisia, Venezuela, Wales Superrnixed - Cameroon, Chad, Hungary Coexistence - France, Niger, Panama p Fusion -None Superposition - Andorra, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Croatia, Georgia, Guinea, Japan, Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Lithuania, Russia, Tajikistan, Ukraine Figure 1: A Classification of Mixed Systems‘52 Ecombined in more than one way in a single election, but one of the mechanisms is compensatory. 2 Figure 1 is a modified version of Massicotte and Blais’ classification. The figure includes countries that did not have mixed systems at the time the article was completed. It also classifies supermixed systems as a form of compensatory system. It further excludes Ecuador, Mexico and Philippines. Ecuador’s system is supermixed, but not compensatory. Mexico uses a fused vote, truly mixed. so its inclusion in the universe of mixed systems is questionable. The Philippines’ system is not This version of the German compensatory mixed system has been in place since 1953 with minor changes in the total number of seats. Because the system has both PR and SMD, it has been the subject of numerous scholarly studies of strategic voting (Barnes et al. 1962; Fisher 1973; Jesse 1988; Bawn 1993; Cox 1997). In these analyses, the difference between a party’s vote in PR and a candidate’s vote in SMD is viewed as a measure of strategic voting. The underlying assumption is that the PR and SMD components are independent and can be analyzed separately. Other scholars have also assumed no interaction, or contamination, between the components of the mixed system (Lancaster and Patterson 1990; Moser 1997, 1999a; Krupavicius 1998; Clark 1999; lshiyama 1999). In some cases, the research design explicitly separates the two components in order to test the effects of PR and SMD on the party system. In other cases, researchers imply that interaction between PR and SMD is not important. While acknowledging the possibility of contamination between the two components of the mixed system in post-communist states, Moser (1997, 1999a) suggests that contamination does not undermine direct comparisons of PR and SMD in mixed systems. He concludes that election outcomes in new democracies may not conform with Duvergerian expectations due to incomplete information among voters and candidates as well as the inchoate nature of the party system. The problems with the assumption of no contamination will be further elaborated in Chapter 2. 50 Seat Distribution in Mixed Systems Mixed systems introduce a complex set of rules that link individual votes to seat allocation in the legislature. In a “pure” version of PR or SMD, the connection between votes and seats is usually clear. Voters in PR are presented the opportunity to vote for a single political party that best represents their policy preferences. Votes are aggregated at the national or regional level and parties receive a proportion of seats that reflects their support in the electorate, contingent upon the electoral threshold and formula for allocation. In an SMD system, voters also have a single choice. They select a candidate to represent the district. The candidate that receives the highest vote total wins the seat.53 Seat allocation in these systems is simple compared to mixed systems. Seat distribution in non-compensatory mixed systems with a single PR district is the most straightforward among the different types of mixed systems. Voters have the opportunity to cast two votes; one is for a party in PR and another is for a candidate in SMD. The winner of each SMD race receives a seat. In the PR component, each party that passes the threshold (if there is one) receives the appropriate number of seats based on the formula. The three systems that are the focus of this analysis use non-compensatory mixed rules. Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine employ an LR-Hare formula to distribute PR seats. The PR threshold in Ukraine is 4%; it is 5% in Lithuania and Russia. 53 In an SMD system with plurality rules, this is the case. In an SMD system with majority-runoff rules, a candidate only wins the seat in the first round if she gains 50% +1 of the votes. If no candidate wins in the first round, a second round is held between the top two candidates from the first round. The candidate winning the plurality in the second round receives the district’s seat. 51 For example, eight parties in Ukraine passed the 4% barrier in the PR component in 1998. They were thus eligible for seats in the PR section. To determine how many seats each party received, a quota was calculated by dividing the number of eligible votes (17,481,593) by the number of seats to be distributed (225), yielding 77,696.54 Votes for parties that did not pass the threshold were not considered in the seat distribution. Each party’s vote total was divided by this quota, and the whole number that resulted determined the number of “full quotas” the party received. This is the first step in the distribution of seats. Table 3 shows the vote in PR received by parties passing the 4% barrier, their quotas and the total number of seats they received in the Rada. Based on the initial seat distribution, 221 of the 225 seats were allocated to parties. The last four seats were allocated based on the fractional component of the parties’ Table 3: Seat Distribution in the Ukrainian Rada (1998) % PR # of Quotas # of Seats KPU 24.65 84.31 84 Rukh 9.40 32.15 32 S&P Bloc 8.56 29.27 29 Greens 5.44 18.59 19 NDP 5.01 17.14 17 Gromada 4.68 15.99 16 PSP 4.05 13.84 14 SDPU 4.01 13.72 14 E 5‘ This is known as a Hare quota. 52 number . largest r( Socialzst In none: aggrega: districts. diSI'lCtS [ T? CSUl‘trteg .‘n .- 'VrmUia W775 ll‘e bETWEe £191,851} 70/ 1 I , 1 m V1 U, I.” (if II J ‘5 (1’ 7.. (17 r _ _ l) (7 " ;. 4P ) (fl .7} .._ rt." -o number of quotas. The first seat was awarded to Gromada because it had the largest remainder (0.99). The next seats were allocated to the Progressive Socialist Party (PSP), the Social Democratic Party (United) and the Greens. In non-compensatory systems with multiple PR districts, PR votes are not aggregated at the national level. Rather, seats are distributed in regional PR districts. Theoretically, parties could choose to participate in only some of the PR districts in this type of system. Japan uses this form of seat distribution.55 The distribution of seats in the SMD component varies slightly among the countries with non-compensatory systems. Russia and Ukraine utilize a plurality formula. The candidate that receives the largest number of votes in the district wins the seat. In Lithuania, a majority-runoff system is used. If no candidate wins a majority (50% plus one vote) in the first round, a second round is held between the top two candidates in the district. The candidate who wins a plurality in the second round takes the district seat. Mixed systems that use compensatory rules distribute seats in a more complex fashion. Under the German system, voters also receive two votes. The first vote is for a candidate in the district-level race. The second vote is for a party in PR. Parties that receive more than 5% of the vote in PR receive seats in the legislature. If a party is unable to pass the 5% threshold, but is able to win 55 Russia uses a hybrid of both national and regional lists to determine seat allocation within parties in PR, but this is distinct from the use of regional lists to allocate seats to parties. In 1999, parties could place eighteen candidates on their national PR lists. Other candidates were placed on regional lists. The party’s overall seat allocation was not affected by this division. Rather, it determined the identity of the candidate who would receive the seat (IFES 1999). 53 568‘. cor: isa unit the :nF .hl Ii In .5? / A i’ seats in three districts, it also receives representation in the party list component.56 The German system strives to distribute seats proportionally. The PR vote is aggregated at the regional (Land) level. Votes are pooled at the national level unless the party specifies otherwise. The number of seats won by the party on the first (SMD) ballot is subtracted from the total number of seats to be allocated in PR for the following calculation. The number of votes received in PR is multiplied by the number of seats in PR minus the number the party won in SMD. This is divided by the sum of all votes in PR. The number that is obtained from this calculation guides seat distribution (Federal Returning Officer 1991). Each party receives the number of seats that match the whole numbers in its index. For example, if a party received an index of 1.5, it would automatically receive one mandate. After these seats are distributed, the remainders are used to allocate remaining seats. If a party receives more seats through constituencies than its proportion of the vote, these are not taken away. Rather, additional seats are created to generate a more proportional distribution of the vote for all parties in the Bundestag. Compensatory systems can also allocate PR seats regionally rather than nationally. For example, Wales has five PR districts. Votes are aggregated at the regional level in each PR district. The d’Hondt formula is used to distribute seats with one qualification. The number of seats won by the party in the SMD component of the region is added to the denominator. This facilitates a more 56 If a party passes neither threshold, it is not represented in the Bundestag. However, candidates that won the SMD seats are allowed to enter partiament as unaffiliated legislators. 54 proporti: I SMD 115 and heir Tr; region ir totals. Ir seats the the hlgi‘fi ICON) WO One, its it won the . aim—t Cl’r‘lru ( t T. ejeCIOia Stab-gt. pg ang- m ."l {1 ' proportionate distribution of seats. If a party wins a large number of seats in SMD, its denominator is raised to a level that prevents it from winning PR seats and being over-represented in parliament. Table 4 shows the process of seat distribution in the Mid and West Wales region in the 1999 elections. The region has four PR seats. In the first and second columns, the parties are identified along with their regional PR vote totals. In the first round, the parties’ vote totals are divided by the number of seats they received in SMD plus one. The first seat is allocated to the party with the highest total after dividing through by the divisor. The Conservative Party (Con) won the first seat. In the second round, the Con’s divisor was raised by one, its index was recalculated, and the next seat was allocated. Again, Con won the seat. In the next round, Con’s total was adjusted and the seat was allocated to the Liberal Democrat Party (LD). The final seat was given to Plaid Cymru (PC). This process was repeated for each regional district. These examples illustrate the complexity of seat distribution in mixed electoral systems. Despite this variation in seat allocation methods, basic strategic incentives should persist across mixed systems. Interaction between PR and SMD should not be sensitive to these aspects of institutional variation. Conclusions This chapter places the basic questions addressed in the dissertation within a broader scholarly context. The literature on institutional design has long This status prevents them from gaining rights accorded to parties in the legislature. 55 .F —fl\(|l.l|l‘ Table 4 - Distribution of Seats in Mid and West Wales Region Party PR Vote Number of Round 1 Number of SMD Seats PR Seats Con 36622 0 36622 1 Green 771 8 0 771 8 0 Ind. Turner 1214 0 1214 0 Lab 53842 2 17947 0 LD 31683 2 1 0561 0 NLP 705 0! 705 0 PC 84554 4 1691 1 0 SocLab 3019 0| 3019 0 Party Round 2 Number of Round 3 Number of PR Seats PR Seats Con 1 831 1 1 61 04 0 Green 771 8 0 771 8 0 Ind. Turner 1214 0 1214 0 Lab 17947 0 1 7947 1 LD 1 0561 0 1 0561 0 NLP 705 0 705 0 PC 1691 1 0 1691 1 0 SocLab 3019 0 3019 0 Party Round 4 Number of PR Seats Con 61 04 0 Green 771 8 0 Ind. Turner 1214 0 Lab 8794 0 LD 10561 0 NLP 705 0 PC 1691 1 1 SocLab 301 9 0 56 have 59 msfrtuhc 0184168 \ The like: Stra‘LEI" r r I :4 x recognized the direct connection between the “rules of the game” and political competition in democratic systems. I focus on electoral systems. The link between electoral rules and the party system is well established in the literature. Duverger's Propositions, although challenged and modified, have served as basic guidelines for predicting party system evolution. Although institutional designers have adopted Duvergerian expectations, the combination of rules with contradictory incentives raises questions about this assumption. The likelihood of interaction between PR and SMD suggests that alternate strategic incentives might emerge, undermining Duvergerian expectations. 57 Chapter 2 THEORETICAL APPROACH AND RESEARCH DESIGN Institutions play a central role in shaping partisan competition. I treat institutional rules as exogenous factors that affect the development of the party system. Although it is well established that existing power arrangements influence the introduction of new institutional rules (Bawn 1993; Remington and Smith 1996), political actors must know and understand the possible consequences of the alternatives for endogeneity to be meaningful. The rules that define the roles political actors play constitute a polity’s institutions (North 1990). Institutions define the environment in which decisions are made and affect the outcomes of those decisions. They limit the actors’ choices by identifying the parameters of accepted behavior. These boundaries can be formal, defined bylaws or other official documents, or informal, established by a culture of behavior generally accepted by participants. By extension, institutions also influence the strategies of political actors. Politicians who understand the rules and boundaries can maximize the probability that they will be successful. In electoral politics, success Is measured first and foremost by gaining elective office. Electoral institutions “weed out” individuals or groups that do not understand the costs and benefits inherent in the system. When developing mixed systems, institutional designers had incomplete information; the potential effects of the mixed system were not well understood. 58 \I'v'i‘ll adva Il'lSiii were HEW’C syster “Sf-3'? inohoa atf'ibut IC the n Election lSExpeC Vt Dames p Strategjc 1' . he “mo-u While political elites may have selected rules that they thought would provide advantages vis-a-vis their opponents, they could not be certain how these new institutions would affect the development of the political system because there were few practical examples to study.57 The institutional rules chosen in many new democracies in the 19905 differed from the few existing examples of mixed systems. Scholars have posited various reasons for the failure of many mixed systems to produce a small number of parties. The large number of parties and inchoate nature of party systems in countries using mixed rules has been attributed to the unique qualities of initial elections. Before political actors adapt to the new incentives of the system, the number of parties can be quite large. As elections take place over time, the number of parties participating in the system is expected to decline.58 While this argument may explain, in part, the relatively large number of parties participating in elections in post-communist states, I contend that the strategic incentives of the mixed system also contribute to multipartism. Despite the unique qualities found in new democracies and incomplete information among participants in the political system, incentives created by mixed electoral rules also affect the development of party systems. 57 In addition, some designers did not analyze the existing systems before selecting mixed electoral rules. Viktor Sheynis, the author of the electoral law in Russia, indicated that he and his colleagues did not study the German system until one year after they adopted the mixed system in Russia (personal conversation with Viktor Sheynis, November 30, 1999). 58 Turner (1993) contradicts this argument by asserting that initial post-authoritarian elections cannot be characterized as more volatile than later elections. 59 Sl’Siem 14 TI" SMD m P the Other As I explained in the previous chapter, the incentives for voters and parties favor the creation of a two-party system at the district level in SMD and a multiparty system in PR, according to Duverger. When they are combined into a single system, two possibilities emerge. The incentives of PR and SMD may be independent, with PR providing incentives for small parties to participate in elections and SMD reducing their number in the districts. The underlying assumption of this possibility is that decisions of voters and politicians in PR are not affected by SMD and decisions in SMD are not affected by PR. Further, individuals and organizations with resources will determine whom they will support in SMD independent of the strength of the party in PR (and vice versa). Lastly, this approach assumes that elite-level strategies in SMD (i.e., candidate placement) will not be affected by concerns for the potential effect on PR. In this model, either PR or SMD incentives could dominate the overall system. If PR were to dominate, we would expect a multiparty system to emerge. If SMD incentives were stronger, we would expect that a two-party system would emerge over time in the districts. The alternate possibility is that there is contamination between PR and SMD in mixed systems. Contamination is one ballot component’s influence on the other. Rather than acting independently, the incentives produced in PR and SMD are combined and together affect the decisions of voters and political elites. 6O Logic of Contamination Effects The imprecise logic of the “no contamination” argument can be best illustrated through an analogy. The suggestion that there is no contamination across components of the mixed system is equivalent to the Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA) assumption in multinomial logit models. If one were attempting to model an individual voter’s choice for a party or candidate, the dependent variable would be the party/candidate selected by the voter. In multiparty systems, multinomial logit would provide an appropriate alternative for modeling choice with more than two discrete, unordered options.59 However, the IIA assumption in multinomial logit results in an imprecise model of the underlying process. In a standard IIA scenario, the ratio of the probability of choosing one party to another party is not altered by the entry of a third party that is considered to be indistinguishable from one of the participating parties. Assume that we have a country in which there are four parties in competition (A-D) and that parties A and B are liberal, and C and D are conservative. Further assume that the only dimension of partisan conflict is the liberal/conservative dimension. In district 1, parties A and C are in competition.‘50 The IIA assumption states that the entry of party D (or party B) would not alter the ratio of probabilities of a voter selecting party A or C. Thus: 5” See Whitten and Palmer (1996) for an example. so This could either represent a single SMD race or a national PR competition. In other words, the model fits both standard PR and SMD systems. 61 PIA |S[A,C] = PIA IS[A,C,D] Pic|S[A,c] PiC|S[A,C,D] where S is the choice set and the terms in brackets represent the elements of the choice set. Under the IIA assumption, the ratio of probability of selecting A to C is not changed by the entry of party D. If, for instance, the probability that the ith voter will select party A is 50% (PM = .50) and the probability that he will choose party C is 50% (Pic = .50), then the ratio of probabilities is Pi = 1.0. If party D (a second conservative party) iC enters the race, two conservative parties would be competing. While the probability of selecting a conservative party may remain .50, we would anticipate that the probability of selecting party C would be altered, especially if parties C and D are viewed as essentially identical. If the selection of the conservative party were random, then the probability of selecting C would become .25 and the probability of selecting D would become .25. The resulting ratio of probabilities would also change, violating the IIA assumption (Alvarez and Nagler 1997, 13). Suggesting that the process of selecting a party in PR is independent of candidate selection in SMD in mixed systems presents a similar challenge to logic. Assume that parties A-D participate in PR61 but do not place candidates in all SMD districts. Assume again that parties A and B are considered to be liberal, parties C and D are considered to be conservative, and that this is the only salient dimension of partisan conflict. In district 1, candidates from party A 62 and p from r: select; C0813? where 5 district g Olf‘ier WC in PR d: dlstrrct, and party C compete. Under the assumption of no contamination, if a candidate from party D enters competition in district 1, the relative probability of a voter selecting between parties A and C in PR should not change. Under no contamination, we would expect the following: PIA", ISPR U SSMD[A,C] _ Pmm ISPR U SSMD[A,C,D] Prom |SPR U SSMD[A,C] Prom ISPR U SSMD[A,c,o] where Spa is the choice set within PR, SSMD is the choice set within the SMD district and the terms in brackets represent the parties competing in SMD. In other words, the ratio of the probability of the ith voter choosing party A to party C in PR does not change when choices are added to the SMD district and/or PR district. If the process of choosing a party in PR and a candidate in SMD is viewed as a single act, then the IIA/no contamination assumption is incorrect. In mixed systems, the implicit assumption of no contamination is that the ratio of the probability of choosing one party in PR to another party is not altered by the entry of another candidate in the SMD component. Contamination effects suggest that this assumption is inappropriate; the introduction of party D’s candidate into SMD should alter the ratio of probabilities of selecting party A or C in PR. That is, 6‘ We will assume that there is one PR district for the entire country. 63 The ratio of change whe assumption assumptions The e contaminatic would expec the PIObabilil e"Dem conta Party in PR if advantage of Arty mi subjeq to bia. PIA”, ISPR USSMD[A,c] PIAPRISPR U SSMD[A,C,D] Prom ISPR U SSMDlA,C] PiCPRISPR U SSMD[A,C,D] The ratio of probability of the it“ voter choosing party A to party C is likely to change when choices are added to either the SMD or PR choice set. The assumption of no contamination is thus analogous to a violation of IIA assumptions. The equivalence of the IIA assumption to the assumption of no contamination can be extended beyond individual voter behavior. Just as we would expect the entry of additional parties/candidates into competition to alter the probability that voters would support a particular party/candidate, we would expect contamination to alter elite behavior. If voters are more likely to support a party in PR if the party fields a candidate in SMD, parties should strive to take advantage of this incentive. Any model that assumes IIA where the assumption is inappropriate is subject to bias. Not only can parameter estimates can be incorrect, but the actual decision-making process is improperly modeled. Similarly, assuming no contamination in voter and elite decision-making leads to an inaccurate representation of the processes at work. Just as the IIA assumption in multinomial logit models is not logical, the assumption of no contamination is not logical in mixed systems. Given that contamination is a logical outgrowth of mixed systems, how would we expect party elites to behave? 64 Party Stratr Prior affect their I. whether to p decisions er and technica as well as th wzth other lik ilmust deteri In a rr PR and SMD Candidates lr Other Parties Candidates, tc system Shoot the PR and S interdepende Denys DOIem Party Strategy Under Mixed Electoral Rules Prior to parliamentary elections, parties must make many decisions that affect their likelihood of entering parliament. Among the most critical decisions is whether to participate in the elections and if so, how they will participate. Entry decisions are based on the party’s assessment of its material, financial, human and technical resources, its ability to meet its electoral and non-electoral goals, as well as the competitive environment and opportunities for coalition-building with other like-minded organizations. Once the party has decided to participate, it must determine how it will participate in the elections. In a mixed system, parties must determine how they will participate in the PR and SMD components of the ballot, how resources will be divided between candidates in these components, and if strategic arrangements can be made with other parties locally or nationally. The leadership must also prepare a slate of candidates to participate in the party list and the district races. The mixed system encourages parties to construct strategies that are conditioned on both the PR and SMD components. These decisions are consequently interdependent. They are influenced by three factors: the electoral rules, the party’s potential resources, and external conditions. All parties are subject to the same electoral rules. While the application of these rules may be subject to bias that benefits some organizations at the expense of others, the rules themselves are the same.62 Across mixed systems, 62 Arguably, powerful or well-connected political organizations may benefit from biased interpretations of electoral rules at the national or local levels. For example, in the 1999 Russian paniamentary elections, some regional governors used their influence with local electoral committees to undermine the candidacy of parties competing against their preferred organization. 65 variation in influence de threshold in influence wl races. A hig through the participants The t} National PR Opportunities list IS Used, u are mOre like present the p ImDI’OVeS a Ca paws reg Ion atom potent]; salley the par Ballot S variation in rules can influence party strategies. Thresholds in PR or SMD influence decisions about the party list and candidate placement. A lower threshold in PR increases the likelihood of gaining seats in parliament and can influence who obtains a high ranking on the list and who participates in SMD races. A higher threshold increases the risk that the party will not gain seats through the PR component, encouraging expanded participation in SMD among participants on the PR list. The type of PR list also potentially alters the strategic decisions of parties. National PR lists, regional PR lists or hybrid PR lists present different opportunities for seat acquisition and should affect list construction. If a national list is used, the highest ranked seats are the “safest” — candidates ranked higher are more likely to receive a seat in the legislature. Regional or hybrid lists present the party with a more complex environment. While higher list placement improves a candidate’s opportunity of receiving a seat, this is conditioned on the party’s regional performance. Parties must collect more detailed information about potential regional performance in order to construct regional lists that will satisfy the party’s candidate pool. Ballot structure also influences party strategy. The type of information about candidates printed on the ballot can alter placement decisions in PR or SMD. The PR list can contain information about the party and information about the top candidates on the list. The SMD ballot can include personal, professional, party or other information. This information can influence where In addition, the media arguably played an active role promoting some parties nationally and locally. While the legal environment was the same for all parties during the campaign, the actual 66 candidate specific di. Wh. party. A p; resource. I outcomes II the election another org lnforr decision abc Placed in ~55 districts in wI candidate ma Daffy list. In 1 "ill; MnGiless of candidates are placed on the PR list and which candidates contest seats in specific districts. While the rules are constant in the system, resources vary from party to party. A party’s popularity at the national and regional levels is a powerful resource. Reliable data about national-level popularity helps parties predict vote outcomes in PR and construct the PR list. If a party expects to perform poorly in the election based on aggregate popularity data, it may choose to coalesce with another organization. Information about the regional distribution of popularity can inform the decision about candidate placement in the districts. Popular candidates may be placed in “safe” districts and young, untested politicians may be nominated in districts in which the party expects to perform poorly.“3 Alternatively, a popular candidate may be placed in an at-risk district, but given a high ranking on the party list. In this way, the candidate may attract voters in the district, but is guaranteed a legislative seat if the party crosses the electoral threshold. The willingness of candidates to accept such a task will vary, but the mixed system presents parties and candidates an opportunity to “hedge their bets” in a way that is not available in standard PR or SMD systems. The number and identity of prominent candidates under the party label is another resource. Party “stars” can include prominent politicians, well-known cultural figures or friends and relatives of prominent political actors. If these individuals bring substantial financial resources to the party in addition to their golitical environment sometimes favored one organization over its rivals. This assertion assumes that the electoral rules do not include a residency requirement. 67 “star qualit mSMD.k campaign f in a well-co does not 56 Nevertheles ranking to b lApar well-develop Candidate pl Organizamn MOVGOver, lh SMD ”Omina a large ”Umbi range of norm Dames dO not i a .aige ”Umbe Camdldage D00] nc- . The final nefaqOrS als I IF.“ Elicia, benef ' E “star quality,” they may be able to influence placement decisions on the PR list or in SMD. In some cases, these individuals may not wish to participate in a campaign fully, but are willing to donate their image to the party. This may result in a well—connected politician receiving a prominent position on the PR list that does not seem justified by the individual’s history of loyalty to the organization. Nevertheless, the party is willing to provide a prominent individual with a high ranking to benefit from “star power” or from the individual’s financial investment. A party’s regional organization is also a potential resource. Parties with well-developed and financed local organizations may assert more influence over candidate placement than organizations with weak regional affiliates. As local organizations are more autonomous, they can influence list construction. Moreover, the party’s central organization may have limited control over local SMD nominations if it has powerful local affiliates. The party’s cadre of potential candidates is another resource. Parties with a large number of credible, experienced and popular politicians have a wider range of nomination options. Particularly in new democracies, some political parties do not have enough credible members interested in seeking office to field a large number of candidates in either PR or SMD. The size of the credible candidate pool thus becomes an important issue for parties and affects nomination patterns in PR and SMD. The financial support enjoyed by the party and the identity of its benefactors also potentially influence decisions about candidate nominations. Financial benefactors may require parties to provide spaces for particular 68 candidate capable 0: Par itself. The party. The parties are same elect: Component candidate p their slates .- SIgrlature (:0 environment To rec form Strategn agree to dlwc fielding a Slhg redUce the “k! "7 Sum. COhSlItUte the l i0d_ Wme the Same f Der candidates on the PR or SMD slate. Also, well-financed parties are more capable of participating in a larger number of SMD races. Party resources are, to a certain degree, within the control of the party itself. The external conditions, however, cannot be influenced directly by the party. The most important external factor is the competitive environment - what parties are competing in the election and to what degree they draw from the same electoral base as the party in question. Further complicating this component of the political environment is that parties must make decisions about candidate placement simultaneously. Parties cannot wait for competitors to form their slates and then react; efforts to gain access to the ballot often require signature collection or resource gathering. Consequently, the competitive environment is not fully known at the time candidate slates are presented. To reduce uncertainty, parties that compete for the same electorate could form strategic alliances that fall short of merger. For example, parties might agree to divide some or all SMD districts in order to avoid splitting the vote. By fielding a single candidate who appeals to a particular constituency, the parties reduce the likelihood that votes will be split among candidates with similar views. In sum, the rules, potential party resources and external environment constitute the initial conditions faced by political organizations during the electoral period. While the party resources vary, the rules and external environment are the same for all. All of these conditions affect the nomination process and mixed electoral rules influence the role that these factors play in strategic decision- making. 69 featUres strategfe under‘h‘ electOral included i analyze in competmol from the ‘0' The ‘ incenllves' on the deve; cadre 0f ideo Parties may a Particular Sho’ Party el by the system- with scholarly e understood by P manifest themse- The organ. This analysis emphasizes the behavior of political parties. The unique features of mixed systems complicate the study of political parties and party strategies. Much of the data from mixed systems comes from initial elections under these electoral rules. Some scholars argue that first elections under a new electoral system are highly problematic (Pedersen 1983) and should not be included in cross-national analyses (Maguire 1983). Although others specifically analyze initial post-authoritarian elections (Turner 1993), the structure of partisan competition and the behavior of parties in first elections may substantially deviate from the long-term equilibrium. The behavior of parties may not solely respond to immediate institutional incentives. Some groups may focus on short-term seat maximization and others on the development of strong regional organizations, a healthy financial base, a cadre of ideologically committed followers or some other long-term strategy. Parties may also miscalculate and pursue strategies that are intended to fulfill particular short- or long-term goals, but are unsuccessful. Party elites may not fully understand the institutional incentives presented by the system. Consequently, strategies in the initial election may not conform with scholarly expectations because the system’s incentives are not yet well understood by political actors. Over time, however, different behaviors will manifest themselves. The organizational capacity of parties may vary. Some parties may have tighter control over ballot access than others; some may have strong local organizations while others have weak local bases; and some parties may 70 inter?“one ideolOQ’Cé Parties to analysis” DeS information focusing] on parties Und‘ data with qu Russia and ( general strati Research De Research HYI l evalua effects and eve upon each othe intentionally field “covert” partisans who eschew the official party label but are ideologically linked with the party. As a result, we would expect the capacity of parties to respond to the system’s incentives to vary, complicating cross-national analysis. Despite these problems, the study of parties can provide valuable information about organizational adaptation to institutional change. Rather than focusing on the strategies of individual parties, I will emphasize the tendencies of parties under different institutional constraints. I will complement the statistical data with qualitative information gathered from discussions with party officials in Russia and Ukraine. The core analysis of the dissertation, however, will focus on general strategies rather than the specific strategies of any given party. Research Design Research Hypotheses I evaluate three hypotheses to assess the credibility of contamination effects and evaluate their impact on strategic incentives. The hypotheses build upon each other to define the strategic incentives presented to political parties in mixed electoral systems. The first hypothesis assesses the strength of the mechanical effect in mixed systems. If mixed systems have a mechanical effect that is less punishing to marginal parties than the mechanical effect in SMD systems, we would expect continued participation by small parties. The second hypothesis illustrates the incentives presented to parties for participation in both components of the mixed system. Because parties can 71 choose to pa have a choic encourages should be ex Duverger's L The tt the SMD cor limit the num Performance mixed Syster Candidates u multiparty Co as a Whole, I use c that Vary In 9 rules, Data E Assessmg thi robustneSS 0 8'5 Eff Q ~Cts are the choose to participate in the PR, SMD or both components of the election, they have a choice about how fully to participate in the system. If the mixed system encourages participation in both components of the mixed system, multipartism should be evidenced in the PR and SMD components, despite the predictions of Duverger's Law. The third hypothesis addresses how fully political parties will participate in the SMD component. Resources and strategic alliances between parties may limit the number of districts in which parties field candidates. However, if performance in PR is positively affected by candidate placement in SMD, the mixed system generates pressures for parties to maximize the number of candidates they sponsor in the SMD component. This should also encourage multiparty competition in both components of the mixed system and the system as a whole. I use data from national parliamentary elections in nine mixed systems that vary in geography, degree of party system institutionalization and electoral rules. Data availability prevents the inclusion of each system in every test. Assessing the hypotheses in various systems, however, allows us to evaluate the robustness of the findings. Contamination effects should be evident in all mixed systems, regardless of the minor variations in institutional rules. If contamination effects are manifested in all of the mixed systems in this study, we can be more confident that they are a product of mixed electoral rules. 72 Case Selection and Data Sources Inherent in the comparative enterprise is the need to choose the specific cases for analysis; it is rarely possible to include the entire universe of all possible cases. Consequently, comparative research is Open to bias emanating from the manner in which cases are chosen for analysis. A further complication to case selection is that mixed electoral systems are not “rare events” cross-nationally, but they are rare longitudinally. In all but a few countries, only a single election has been held under these rules. While short-term effects theoretically can be analyzed cross-nationally, long-term effects can be addressed in a limited number of cases. Data availability also restricts case selection among mixed systems. While aggregate data are available for many mixed systems, district level data are less accessible.64 In addition, the diversity of languages complicates the collection and interpretation of data. While data from nine countries will be employed, the analysis will focus on three post-communist states: Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine. The availability of appropriate data in these states facilitates a consistent analysis across all hypotheses. Data from six other political units, Armenia, Germany, Japan, New Zealand, Scotland and Wales, will be presented in the appendices to confirm that the incentive structures found in the non-compensatory systems of Lithuania, 6" The use of district-level election data is appropriate both theoretically and practically. This analysis investigates strategic incentives provided to parties at the district-level. Duverger’s Propositions are district-level concepts; using aggregate data to estimate the effects of a district level process is inappropriate. Further, the employing district level data in the analysis does not introduce a problem of ecological inference. The individual tendencies of voters are not assessed in this analysis. Rather, the central tendencies of performance that guide the activities of political actors are under investigation. The data and underlying mechanism are both district-level. 73 Russia and Ukraine are not limited to a particular sub-type of mixed systems or to new democracies. The analysis seeks to provide a comprehensive picture of strategic incentives and party behaviors in a few mixed systems, but additional evidence will help to demonstrate whether the conclusions are generalizable. Mechanical Effect Hypothesis The first step in understanding party strategies under mixed electoral rules is to determine how marginal parties should react to the system based on its mechanical effect. Duverger’s Propositions provide different predictions about the behavior of parties based, in part, on how the mechanical effect influences the possibilities for small parties to gain legislative representation. In a PR system, small parties are more likely to gain seats because performance in the aggregate is emphasized; they are less likely to gain seats in SMD because candidates must win a plurality in a single electoral district in order to win a seat. How does the combination of these rules in mixed systems affect the electoral fortunes of marginal political organizations? The Mechanical Effect hypothesis states that the mechanical effect in mixed systems is more forgiving to small parties than the mechanical effect in SMD systems. If this hypothesis finds support in the data, the mixed system produces an incentive structure that does not undermine the participation of small parties. That is, the mechanical effect does not produce cues for small parties to abandon participation. This should have an impact on the 74 psychological effect, reducing the likelihood that mixed systems will produce two- party competition at the district level. In order to assess this hypothesis, I first evaluate a measure of disproportionality with data from Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine. The calculation of disproportionality is straightforward - the proportion of seats gained by a party is divided by the proportion of votes received by the party.65 The resulting index provides some insight into the system’s mechanical effect. An index of 1.00 indicates that the party’s representation in parliament is perfectly proportional because the percentage of seats gained is exactly equal to the percentage of votes accrued. If parties that receive a relatively small amount of the vote are represented proportionately, they should not be dissuaded from participating in future elections. The best way to represent the mechanical effect is derived from these calculations of disproportionality. Proportionality profiles and break even points allow us to view the mechanical effect on a two-dimensional figure. The proportionality profile assesses the degree to which the mechanical effect punishes small parties. Applying the scatterplot smoother loess (Hastie and Tibshirani 1990), I will demonstrate that proportionality profiles of mixed systems do not conform with the proportionality profiles typically associated with SMD systems.66 65 This measure of disproportionality is labeled the Advantage Ratio by Taagepera and Shugart (1989). It assesses the proportionality of seat allocation for each individual party. Other measures of disproportionality, like the Least Squares Index of Disproportionality, calculate the groportionality of seat allocation for the entire system. I use standard proportionality profiles derived from empirical data by Taagepera and Shugart (1989). 75 The analysis will show that the mechanical effect in mixed systems is less punishing to marginal parties than the mechanical effect in SMD. Consequently, the mixed system provides an incentive structure that does not undermine participation by small parties or independents. While the total number of parties in competition may be reduced somewhat over time, it should not mimic an SMD system. Investment Effect Hypothesis The first form of contamination encourages parties to participate in both components of the mixed system and can be called the Investment Effect. When a political organization decides to participate in an electoral campaign in a mixed system, it can support candidates in SMD only, in PR only, or in both PR and SMD. The Investment Effect encourages parties to select the third option: participation in both PR and SMD. Theoretically, a party could participate only in the SMD portion of the mixed system. However, pursuing this strategy would place the party at a disadvantage vis-a-vis parties that also participate in PR. Some benefits accorded to political parties often are not conferred to parties that fail to register in PR. Participation in the SMD component alone does not facilitate seat maximization by political parties. The second approach is to participate in PR only. If parties aim to maximize the number of legislative seats in parliament, this approach is also not logical. Parties must make a substantial investment of resources to mount a 76 campaign in PR. Because the marginal cost of participating in some SMD races should not be high, given that the party already has an administrative structure, some fundraising capabilities, and some committed politicians campaigning for it at the national level, parties can maximize seat acquisition by participating in both PR and SMD. Participation in SMD should be dictated, in part, by the ability of parties to overcome costs of committing to electoral competition. Parties with a greater ability to overcome the additional costs of participation in SMD should participate to a greater degree than those with more limited resources. The Investment Effect Hypothesis thus states that the decision of parties to participate in PR will encourage some level of participation in SMD. If this is so, parties participating in PR should place multiple candidates in SMD races. In addition, parties with greater resources should participate more fully in SMD than those with fewer resources. The hypothesis is evaluated in two ways. First, I will present the SMD candidate placement patterns of parties in Lithuania (1996), Russia (1993, 1995 and 1999) and Ukraine (1998) to demonstrate that parties committing to PR tend to participate in both PR and SMD. Second, I will employ OLS regression analysis to show that a party’s resources are directly related to SMD participation. Parties that are more able to overcome resource restrictions are likely to participate in a higher proportion of SMD races. Data from the most recent parliamentary elections in Lithuania (1996), Russia (1999) and Ukraine (1998) are employed to evaluate the second aspect 77 of the Investment Effect Hypothesis. The unit of analysis is political parties and each party that participated in the PR component is included.67 The dependent variable is the proportion of districts in which SMD candidates are placed and is labeled SMDPER. Three independent variables are included to reflect a party’s resource base. While information about financial resources is not generally available, I have developed proxies for other resources. The variable PRLIST measures the party’s personnel resources. Parties that have more candidates on their PR list have greater personnel resources and should be able to place candidates in a higher proportion of districts than parties with a smaller contingent of capable politicians. The variable is an interval-level measure of the proportion of total PR seats covered by the party’s PR list.68 The explanatory variable PRVOTE measures the party’s level of support in the electorate. Parties with greater levels of grassroots support should also have more resources. While this variable is problematic temporally, it is the best proxy for support in the electorate that could be developed for this analysis. It is also interval level. Lastly, the variable PREVELECT is a dummy variable measuring participation in previous elections. Parties with a longer electoral history should have better-developed local organizations than parties that are new and thus should be more capable of overcoming additional costs of SMD participation. 67 In Lithuania, some parties participated in PR but did not submit their lists to the Electoral Commission to participate in open list PR. These parties were omitted from the analysis. 68 Proportions, rather than raw numbers, are used because Lithuania’s partiament has fewer seats allocated to PR than parliaments in Russia or Ukraine. 78 The variable is coded “1” if the party participated in the previous election and “0” if the party did not participate. The model for this hypothesis is thus: SMDPER = or + BIPRLIST + BzPRVOTE + BgPREVELECT + e The Investment Effect suggests that a political party’s commitment to participation in PR and its level of resources directly affect participation in SMD. Furthermore, multipartism should be produced in the SMD component of mixed systems. Echo Effect Hypothesis Whereas the Investment Effect asserts that resources dictate party behavior, the Echo Effect focuses on indirect effects that encourage parties to participate in as many SMD races as resources allow. The PR electoral benefits that can accrue to parties that participate in SMD races further encourage multipartism. The Echo Effect describes an interaction that affects electoral outcomes directly and party strategies indirectly. When a party sponsors a candidate in an SMD race, the affiliation of a party with a local candidate could improve performance in PR at the SMD district level. The candidate’s campaign would raise awareness of the party locally, increasing the likelihood that the party would receive votes in the PR component of the ballot. The Echo Effect Hypothesis states that the placement of candidates in SMD will affect vote outcomes in 79 PR in corresponding districts. The positive effect of SMD placement on parties’ PR performance should further encourage parties to maximize the placement of candidates in SMD. The empirical test evaluates the effects of SMD candidate placement on local PR performance and controls for rival hypotheses. There are two major rival explanations to the Echo Effect. The first is that the direction of causality in the model is incorrect. SMD candidate placement may not affect PR performance; rather, SMD placement could be a response to evaluations of party popularity. That is, parties place SMD candidates where the leadership knows that the party enjoys a high level of popularity. If the rival explanation is correct, the statistical significance of the coefficient for SMD is an artifact of careful candidate placement, not an Echo Effect.69 Another version of this rival explanation is that any significance attributed to candidate placement is an artifact of cleavage structures in the country. Specifically, variation in PR performance is better explained by regionalism than by the Echo Effect. In a society with strong regional cleavages, the parameter value for SMD placement may be statistically significant due to regionalism. I use data from Ukraine, a country with established regional cleavages, to evaluate this rival hypothesis. Regionalism could undermine confidence in the existence of the Echo Effect in the following way. Let us say that we have a country with four parties 69 This rival hypothesis could be rejected on logical grounds. The degree of electoral volatility in post-Communist states undermines the argument that parties have complete district level information about where they are popular. Nevertheless, the models include controls for this rival explanation. 8O that partici strong in d D has the I Tr that participate in PR (A, B, C and D) and six districts (1-6). Party D is regionally strong in districts 1 and 2 and only runs SMD candidates in those districts. Party D has the following distribution of candidates and PR performance: Table 5: Hypothetical Distribution of Candidates and Votes D 1 D 2 D 3 D 4 D 5 D 6 SMD 1 1 O O 0 0 PR Vote 50% 50% 10% 10% 10% 10% In this case, we would find that the variable SMD is related to the dependent variable PR Vote. However, we do not know if this is due to the Echo Effect (candidate placement), the regional strength of Party D in districts 1 and 2, or some combination of the two. There is well-established literature about regionalism in Ukraine and the effect of regionalism on politics in the post-Soviet period. While other countries using mixed systems may display some elements of regional cleavages, regionalism has not been a major force in their party systems.7o Regionalism has been an important force in Ukrainian politics, however. During the 1994 presidential race, the eventual winner, Leonid Kuchma, catered to the East’s preference for closer ties with Russia. His competitor, Leonid Kravchuk, promoted distancing Ukraine from Russia. Kuchma won the East; Kravchuk the West (Holdar 1995; Solchanyk 1995). In the 1998 parliamentary elections, 7° Russia, in particular, has experienced regional conflict. War in the Caucasus region and the negotiation of various bilateral treaties between ethnic regions and Moscow underscores some of Russia’s divisions (Ordeshook and Shvetsova 1995). However, these regional cleavages have not yet been manifested in the party system. In contrast to Russia, regionalism in Ukraine is 81 certain pa nafionahs Assembly Parties lik fondness ; 2000) Anc contaminal Electoral cc the PFOport Russian e15 aCtuauy “Co i”dependen We“? COntr affiliation. bL COnfidenCe n Effeq If the a is we'l‘khowr a statisjmauy an d 'OCai pen. 53% certain parties constructed their messages to appeal to the West. Ukrainian nationalist parties or blocs, such as the National Front or the Ukrainian National Assembly, emphasized ethnicity and language to appeal to Western voters. Parties like the Progressive Socialist Party, that view the Soviet period with great fondness and nostalgia, targeted the East (Craumer and Clem 1999; Kubicek 2000) Another issue that potentially undermines confidence in the existence of contamination is the large number of independents that have participated in electoral contests. Only Lithuania has a small number of unaffiliated candidates; the proportion of independent candidates exceeds 35% in Ukraine and all three Russian elections.71 It is very likely that some “independent” candidates are actually “covert partisans” (Moser 1999b). That is, they are not truly independent, but have a partisan affiliation that is masked in the coding. Local voters, contributors and other candidates may be aware of the candidate’s true affiliation, but it is not captured in the data. If covert partisanship undermines confidence in the coding, it could also threaten the validity of the test for the Echo Effect. If the affiliation of “covert partisans” with the party that is sponsoring them is well-known and substantially affects voter perceptions, we would expect to find a statistically significant relationship between a measure of covert partisanship and local performance in PR. By adding a variable that controls for covert reflected in the party system and its effects have been addressed in scholarly works (Barrington 1997; Craumer and Clem 1999). 71 In Russia, 58% of the SMD candidates were independent in 1993; 35% in 1995 and 47% in 1999. In Ukraine's 1998 elections, 48% of the SMD candidates were unaffiliated. 82 partisans attenuate Th analyzed performan model of ti participate: The ability 1 underminec standpoint. i COmpeted in 8temples of MOdeIs 1a a] MOdejs for the first rive ”the party War With the Party 5 934 dance 0f the to . W Van . at » . ‘3th 0n thepan'Cl Van; C partisans, we can assess the degree to which this impacts PR performance or attenuates the Echo Effect. The Echo Effect is evaluated on the level of political parties. Each party is analyzed separately to gauge the precise effect of candidate placement on PR performance. Because parties vary in size and relative performance, a pooled model of the entire system would provide less useful results. All parties that participated in at least 20% of the SMD districts are included in the analysis.72 The ability to assess the relationship between placement and performance is undermined if parties run in very few, or virtually all, districts. From a practical standpoint, this requirement tends to eliminate many of the “micro parties" that competed in the newly independent states of the former Soviet Union. However, examples of both small and large parties for each country remain in the analysis. Models 1a and 1b: Echo Effect Hypothesis with Controls for Popularity Models 1a and 1b evaluate the existence of the Echo Effect and control for the first rival explanation. The dependent variable is performance in PR at the SMD level and is labeled PRPER. SMDPL is a dummy variable that is coded “1” if the party placed a candidate in the district and “0” if no candidate was affiliated with the party. If the SMD coefficient is statistically significant, it demonstrates that placement of candidates in SMD directly affects PR performance and is evidence of the Echo Effect’s existence. 72 Parties that participated in over 80% of the districts were also eliminated to ensure some variation on the variable SMDPL. 83 A may hav The van; candidate Cc adequate proxies. F the district Characteris OfRussia, , to PErform i that attract i Parties are S Calidldates i The v DOPUIanty. E CENSUS an d E are at the Obi f ,. . ‘e’mollal Wilts u ,; fits matCh thé al~ so mater, CUn A control for incumbency is also included to account for candidates who may have greater resources and are more established in their party and region. The variable INCUMBENT is coded “1” if the candidate is an incumbent; “0” if the candidate is not an incumbent. Controls for popularity are also added the models. Because there are no adequate measures of district-level popularity for the former Soviet states, I use proxies. Parties may have limited information about their relative popularity at the district level, but base some of their placement decisions on demographic characteristics of the region. For example, agrarian parties (i.e., Agrarian Party of Russia, Agrarian Party of Ukraine, Lithuanian Peasants’ Party) should expect to perform well in rural areas and poorly in urban regions. Conversely, parties that attract working class support should expect to perform well in cities. Liberal parties are generally expected to appeal to more educated voters and may place candidates in regions with a more educated population. The variables URBAN and EDUCATION are added as proxies for popularity. Both variables are based on data obtained from the 1989 Soviet census and are aggregated at different levels. For Russia and Ukraine, the data are at the oblast level. This unit is roughly comparable to a US state. There are 89 units in Russia, most of which are oblasts (provinces). There are also territorial units called “krais” and “okrugs” which are included as well. The 89 units match the 89 regions in the current Russian system. The Ukrainian oblasts also match current administrative divisions. There are 27 of these units in total. 84 map of matche geogra; T region th of the reg variables. regional le analysis. ' PRPE Model lb In: Russia and t PRPER =( Lithuanian data are a combination of regional- and city-level data. Using a map of electoral districts obtained from the Lithuanian Electoral Commission, I matched current administrative units with Soviet-era counterparts. These geographic units conform with the 71 electoral districts in Lithuania. The variable URBAN measures the proportion of the population in the region that is made up of urban dwellers. EDUCATION assesses the proportion of the region’s inhabitants that have a higher education. Both are interval level variables. Because Lithuanian entries in the 1989 Soviet census did not include regional level data for education, this control is excluded from the Lithuanian analysis. This constitutes Model 1a: PRPER = or + BISMDPL + leNCUMBENT + B3URBAN + 8 (Model 13) Model 1b includes the variable EDUCATION and is evaluated with data from Russia and Ukraine: PRPER = or + BISMDPL + fileCUMBENT + B3URBAN + B4EDUCATION + a (Model 1b) Model 2: Echo Effect Hypothesis with Controls for Regionalism Model 2 replicates Model 1’s assessment of the Echo Effect and adds control variables for regionalism. The main difference in the country is between the East and West (divided by the Dnieper River). However, the Crimean region and Central region of the country have different characteristics that justify a 85 division of L dummy varii eliminates tl base region the model w PRPEF If the inclusi COrltaminatir and Social C cleavages variables. it MOdeI 3: EC MOde SMD provide ~rirhe a hE 53ng a Ob 8y Viv Ia R n s division of Ukraine into four regions. Regions are thus divided into four separate dummy variables.73 By controlling for regionalism, we can see if it attenuates or eliminates the effects of contamination. The Central region will be used as the base region and its dummy will be excluded from the analysis. Consequently, the model will be the following: PRPER = or + BISMDPL + BZINCUMBENT + B3URBAN + B4EDUCATION + BsCRIMEA + B6EAST + B7WEST + a (Model 2) If the inclusion of regional dummy variables attenuates the effect of contamination (the significance of SMD), it will provide evidence that institutional and social components may interact in countries with substantial regional cleavages. If the effects of SMD remain significant after controlling for these variables, it will show that institutional explanations are robust even in the presence of strong regional cleavages. Model 3: Echo Effect Hypothesis with Controls for Independents Model 3 adds controls for covert partisanship. The Ukrainian ballot for SMD provided voters with the candidate’s name, date of birth, occupation and party membership. The ballot itself did not include party sponsorship, however. Central Electoral Commission data from Ukraine include both the candidate’s 73 The Central region contains: Chemigiv, Cherkaska, Dnipropitrovsk, Kyiv City, Kyiv Region, Kirovograd, Kherson, Mikolaevsk, Odessa, and Poltava oblasts. The Crimean region includes Crimea and Sevastopol. The Eastern region includes Donetsk, Kharkiv, Lugansk, Sumska, and Zaporizka oblasts. The Western region is made up of Chemivets, lvano-Frankivsk, Khmelnitsk, Lviv, Rivnensk, TemOpil, Vinnitsa, Volinska, Zakarpatia, and Zhitomir oblasts. 86 party mei an officia political p independi Thr partisan. question 0 Party mem in Which vc PRPEj ”‘f If Cc paniCtPatiOr is not, then ‘ Contaminatic numbers or i. party membership and the sponsorship. There were numerous cases in which an officially independent candidate (labeled “bezpartiiniy”) was sponsored by a political party. Such a candidate would be labeled on the ballot as an independent.74 The variable COVPART is coded “1” if the district includes only a covert partisan. In such a case, the voter would not see a candidate from the party in question on the ballot itself. It is coded “0” if there is no covert partisan or if a party member also ran in the district. This variable captures only those districts in which voters find no one sponsored by the given party. The model is thus: PRPER = or + BISMDPL + leNCUMBENT + B3URBAN + B4EDUCATION + BsCRIMEA + BsEAST + B7WEST + BsCOVPART + 8 (Model 3) If COVPART is statistically significant and positive in sign, then the participation of covert partisans influences the evaluation of the Echo Effect. If it is not, then the existence of covert partisans has a negligible effect on contamination. In the latter case, we can be confident that the existence of large numbers of independents does not undermine conclusions about contamination. Conclusions The three main hypotheses provide a step-by-step approach to determining the incentive structure of mixed systems and how party systems 7" The candidate’s decision to appear as independent on the ballot could be strategic. Through party sponsorship, the candidate could gain access to resources. However, any negative implications of association with the party could be avoided. 87 should develop based on these incentives. All three hypotheses provide evidence for the continuation of multiparty competition in mixed systems. The Mechanical Effect Hypothesis suggests that marginal parties are likely to participate in mixed systems because the mechanical effect is more forgiving to small parties than the mechanical effect in a “pure” SMD system. This hypothesis will be evaluated in the next chapter. The Investment Effect Hypothesis addresses the question: given that marginal parties will participate in the mixed system, how will they choose to participate? Parties are expected to participate in the system fully — competing for seats in both the PR and SMD components. A constraint on participation in SMD, according to the Investment Effect Hypothesis, is the party’s resources. This hypothesis will be assessed in Chapter 4. The Echo Effect Hypothesis evaluates a related issue: Are resources the primary force guiding candidate placement decisions in SMD? The Echo Effect Hypothesis suggests that parties can benefit in PR from participation in SMD, encouraging parties to place SMD candidates in as many districts as possible. The electoral environment, however, provides an additional constraint on participation in SMD. This hypothesis will be analyzed in Chapter 5. 88 Chapter 3 THE MECHANICAL EFFECT The mechanical effect (the translation of votes into seats) is one of the main factors underlying the development of the party system. This effect occurs in each election and unlike its counterpart, the psychological effect, no time interval must elapse before its implications are known. The primary determinant of the mechanical effect is the mechanism for the allocation of seats in parliament — the electoral rules. Because the mechanical effect demonstrates whether or not marginally performing parties can gain a proportional seat allocation in the legislature, it exerts an important impact on the psychological effect. If marginal parties can gain representation in the legislature, the sources of support for these parties are less likely to disappear in subsequent elections. Voters will continue to support parties that can win, contributors will continue to fund these movements, and prominent politicians are more likely to choose to affiliate with parties that can gain office. Thus, the degree to which the mechanical effect punishes marginal parties is a key to understanding the incentives that mixed systems provide to political parties. Parties take cues from the mechanical effect when assessing the probability of success in an election. If the system punishes marginal parties by under-representing them in parliament, parties may be encouraged to merge with stronger organizations or leave electoral competition altogether. However, 89 if small parties are proportionately represented in the legislature, it provides a signal that the system is conducive to seat acquisition by marginal parties.75 Over time, a system that is punishing to small parties is expected to experience withdrawal by small parties and an overall reduction in the number of parties. A relatively forgiving system should encourage participation by small parties. SMD systems are considered to be more punishing to small parties than PR systems. Because parties must gain a plurality vote in a district to win a race, small parties are placed at a substantial disadvantage. A small party that garners, for example, 10% of the votes in every district, would likely gain no SMD seats. In a PR system, by contrast, a party receiving 10% of the votes would receive approximately 10% of the seats. PR systems thus encourage participation by marginal parties. How does the mechanical effect in mixed systems affect marginal parties? To assess the mechanical effect in the mixed system, the system should be treated as an entity. Rather than calculating the mechanical effect for the PR and SMD components separately, one should combine the results and determine the effect of the entire system. One way to measure the mechanical effect is to use a measure of proportionality. Various measures can be used to assess a system’s proportionality. l utilize the Advantage Ratio (A) which divides the number of seats obtained by the number of votes for each party (Taagepera and Shugart 1989). This 75 It is important to note that parties may vary regarding their motivations to compete in elections. Vlfinning a single seat, rather than a proportional allocation of seats, may satisfy some party leaders. By contrast, a proportional seat allocation may not suffice for some parties that expect 90 measure is useful for two reasons. It allows us to evaluate the proportionality of seat distribution for each party; other measures aggregate individual party values into an overall index for the system. The Advantage Ratio is also used to derive proportionality profiles, detailed later in the chapter. If the value of A is near unity, then the party in question receives a proportion of seats equivalent to its support in the electorate. A number substantially above or below unity indicates that the party is over-represented or under-represented in the legislature. In each of the mixed systems under analysis, the mechanical effect is less punishing than the mechanical effect in SMD. In Lithuania’s 1996 elections, many parties received a proportion of seats roughly equivalent to their support in the electorate (see Table 6).76 The party that received the most votes in 1996, Homeland Union, is over-represented in Lithuania’s parliament (Seimas). Although Homeland Union received 30% of the total vote, it received almost 50% of the seats. This is due primarily to the party’s ability to win many seats in SMD. If results had been based on the first round of the elections alone, the Homeland Union would have been even more highly over-represented. It won a plurality in many districts in the first round of voting, but some of its candidates failed to win the second round. to be over-represented in parliament. Generally, however, parties are assumed to desire an allocation of seats that corresponds with their support in the electorate. 76 Lithuanian results are somewhat problematic in calculating the mechanical effect. Because the SMD component uses a Majority-Runoff system, seat allocation does not take place after the first round. However, because only two parties advance to the second round, the total vote cannot only be calculated with first round results. This analysis uses seat allocation from the final round, but vote totals from the first round. 91 Table 6: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Lithuania 1996 — Second Round)77 Party % Votes % Seats” A’s Homeland Union — Lithuanian Conservatives 30.0 49.6 1.66 Lithuanian Social Democratic Party 7.1 8.5 1.20 Lithuanian Center Union 7.7 9.2 1.19 Lithuanian Christian Democratic Party 11.9 11.3 0.96 Lithuanian National Union 3.0 2.8 0.95 Lithuanian Democratic Labor Party 10.6 8.5 0.81 Lithuanian Poles’ Electoral Alliance 3.0 2.1 0.72 Lithuanian Party of the Economy 1.6 0.7 0.43 Lithuanian Union of Political Prisoners and Deportees 1.7 0.7 0.42 Lithuanian Peasants’ Party 2.0 0.7 0.35 Lithuanian Liberal Union 2.3 0.7 0.31 Christian Democratic Union 2.4 0.7 0.30 New Democracy/Women’s Party 3.4 0.7 0.21 Lithuanian National Party “Young Lithuania” 4.4 0.7 0.16 Lithuanian Citizens’ Alliance 2.1 0.0 0.00 Union of Russians of Lithuania 1.3 0.0 0.00 Lithuanian Freedom Union 1.3 0.0 0.00 Lithuanian Freedom League 0.7 0.0 0.00 Lithuanian Union of Social Justice 0.7 0.0 0.00 Lithuanian Socialist Party 0.6 0.0 0.00 Lithuanian Republican Party 0.7 0.0 0.00 Party of National Progress 0.4 0.0 0.00 Lithuanian Party of Life’s Logic 0.3 0.0 0.00 Lithuanian People’s Party 0.2 0.0 0.00 Lithuanian Reform Party 0.0 0.0 0.00 Independent Movement "Elections 96" 0.5 0.0 0.00 77 Source: Electoral Commission of Lithuania. 1999. [Online] http://rc.lrs.lt/rinkimai/, and e—mail with the Electoral Commission of Lithuania. 78 The seat percentage is based on the distribution that occurred after the second round of the SMD component. The total percentage of votes received by parties in the system is based, however, on the first round only in order to preserve the SMD vote totals received by parties that did not pass through to the second round. Using data from only the first round does not produce substantially different results. 79 The Advantage Ratio (A) is a measure of proportionality that is calculated by the dividing the percentage of seats obtained by the percentage of votes obtained (T aagepera and Shugart 1989). 92 The Lithuanian Social Democratic Party (LSDP) and Lithuanian Center Union (LCU) are also over-represented, but less so. Both parties received about 7% of the total votes and 9% of the total seats in the legislature. Although slightly under-represented, the Lithuanian Christian Democratic Party (LCDP) and Lithuanian National Union (LNU) received a proportionate seat allocation. The LCDP and LNU are notable because they achieved a proportionate allocation of seats in different ways. The LCDP performed quite well in both components of the system, receiving seats in PR and SMD. The LNU did not pass the PR threshold, however, and only gained seats in SMD. The ability of parties to gain a proportional allocation of seats in the system, even by failing to pass the PR threshold, provides incentives for small parties to participate. While thresholds are used to dissuade small parties from participating, they can gain seats in parliament despite the threshold, as the LNU demonstrates.80 Results from Russia are similar to those from Lithuania. In 1993, seven of the thirteen parties participating in the election were over-represented or slightly under-represented in the legislature (see Table 7). Russia’s Choice, the Agrarian Party of Russia (APR), Women of Russia and the Communist Party of the Russian Federation (KPRF) were over-represented in the Duma. However, the ratio of seats to votes for the Women of Russia and KPRF was almost perfectly proportional. While they were under-represented, the Liberal 8° Rules in parliament regarding the formation of factions may favor winning seats in PR. Parties that pass the threshold in the PR component can form parliamentary factions that have greater access to committee assignments and other perks. While mechanisms exist for the formation of factions by politicians that are not part of a party that passed the PR threshold, faction formation is more difficult for these legislators. While there are additional incentives to pass the PR threshold, a party’s ability to obtain a proportionate seat allocation only by winning SMD seats should encourage small parties to participate in elections. 93 Democratic Party of Russia (LDPR), Yabloko and Dignity and Charity received close to a proportional seat allocation. While 1995’s Duma elections produced a larger number of over- represented parties than the 1993 elections, the mechanical effect continued to support participation by small political parties (see Table 8). Because only four political parties passed the 5% threshold in PR in 1995, these parties were substantially over-represented in the total system. The KPRF and Yabloko were the main beneficiaries of the distortion. The KPRF received only 19% of the overall vote but 35% of the seats. Yabloko received 5% of the vote, but 10% of the seats. Our Home is Russia (NDR), Power to the People, 89 Regions of Russia and the LDPR were also over-represented. The tiny 89 Regions of Russia electoral bloc gained a single district seat and was over-represented in the Duma. Just as in 1993, a small party was able to gain representation in SMD, resulting in proportional seat acquisition in the whole system. Two other parties were slightly under-represented. The Party of Economic Freedom and APR received a proportionate share of seats. The field narrowed in 1999 and the number of parties receiving a proportional allocation of seats also declined (see Table 9). Five parties were over-represented or slightly under-represented. Fatherland-All Russia (OVR) and the KPRF were over-represented in the Duma, but the general level of over- representation was not as extreme as in 1995. Medved and the Union of Right Forces (SPS) were also over-represented. The Zhirinovskiy Bloc (the 1999 version of the LDPR) was slightly under-represented. Other parties were more 94 Table 7: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Russia 1993)"1 Parties % Votes % Seats A Russia's Choice 12.7 14.6 1.15 Agrarian Party of Russia 7.5 8.3 1.10 Women of Russia 5.0 5.2 1.04 Communist Party of the Russian Federation 9.0 9.2 1.03 Liberal Democratic Party of Russia 14.7 14.4 0.98 Yabloko 6.5 6.1 0.94 Dignity and Charity 0.7 0.7 0.91 Party of Russian Unity and Accord 5.3 4.7 0.89 Democratic Party of Russia 4.4 3.4 0.77 Civic Union 2.7 1.4 0.50 Russian Movement for Democratic Reforms 3.5 1.1 0.32 Future of Russia-New Names 1.1 0.2 0.20 Kedr 0.8 0.0 0.00 8‘ Source: Central Electoral Commission of the Russian Federation (1996); Rossiiskaya Gazeta (1 996). 95 Table 8: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Russia 1995)82 Party % Vote % Seats A Communist Party of the Russian Federation 18.65 34.89 1.87 Yabloko 5.39 10.00 1 .85 Our Home is Russia 8.32 12.22 1.47 89 Regions of Russia 0.17 0.22 1.32 Liberal-Democratic Party of Russia 8.94 11.33 1.27 Power to the People! 1.77 2.00 1.13 Party of Economic Freedom 0.23 0.22 0.99 Agrarian Party of Russia 4.81 4.44 0.92 Bloc of Independents 0.36 0.22 0.62 Party of Russian Unity and Accord 0.38 0.22 0.59 Democratic Choice of Russia 3.44 2.00 0.58 Transformation of the Fatherland 0.40 0.22 0.56 Bloc of Ivan Rybkin 1.42 0.67 0.47 Common Cause 0.49 0.22 0.46 Forward, Russia! 1.73 0.67 0.39 Pamfilova-Gurov-Lysenko 1 .22 0.44 0.36 My Fatherland 0.66 0.22 0.33 Congress of Russian Communities 3.76 1.11 0.30 Bloc of Stanislav Govorukhin 0.86 0.22 0.26 Women of Russia 3.05 0.67 0.22 Union of Labor 1.28 0.22 0.17 Party of Worker Self-Government 2.47 0.22 0.09 Communists-Workers of Russia-for the USSR 3.40 0.22 0.07 Association of Russian Attorneys 0.26 0.00 0.00 Beer Lovers' Party 0.38 0.00 0.00 Christian-Democratic Union 0.23 0.00 0.00 Derzhava 1 .73 0.00 0.00 Duma-96 0.12 0.00 0.00 Electoral Iloc (various parties) 0.14 0.00 0.00 Electoral Bloc 2 (various parties) 0.28 0.00 0.00 Federal-Democratic Movement 0.09 0.00 0.00 For the Motherland! 0.29 0.00 0.00 Generation of the Frontier 0.06 0.00 0.00 lnterethnic Union 0.03 0.00 0.00 Kedr 0.93 0.00 0.00 National-Republican Party of Russia 0.28 0.00 0.00 People's Union 0.16 0.00 0.00 96 82 Source: Central Electoral Commission of the Russian Federation (1996). Table 8 (cont’d) Russian All-National Movement Russian Muslim Movement "Nur" Social Democrats Stable Russia Tikhonov-Tupolev-Tikhonov Union of Housing Construction Workers 0.16 0.33 0.25 0.18 0.09 0.12 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 97 Table 9: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Russia 1999)"3 Party % Votes % Seats A Fatherland—All Russia 1 1.9 15.2 1.28 Communist Party of the Russian Federation 20.9 25.7 1.23 Medved 14.1 16.4 1.16 Union of Right Forces 6.4 6.6 1.03 Zhirinovsky Bloc (LDPR) 4.1 3.9 0.94 Yabloko 6.0 4.5 0.75 Our Home is Russia 2.2 1.6 0.73 Movement in Support of the Army 0.7 0.5 0.64 Russian National Union 0.8 0.5 0.57 Spiritual Heritage 0.6 0.2 0.41 Russian Socialist Party 0.7 0.2 0.34 Congress of Russian Communities 0.7 0.2 0.32 Bloc of Andrei Nikolayev and Svyatoslav Fyodorov 0.9 0.2 0.26 Party of Pensioners 1.5 0.2 0.15 All-Russian Party of the People 0.1 0.0 0.00 Communists—Workers of Russia—for the USSR 1.5 0.0 0.00 Conservative Party of Russia 0.1 0.0 0.00 For Citizens’ Dignity 0.5 0.0 0.00 Party of Peace and Unity 0.2 0.0 0.00 Peace, Labor, May 0.4 0.0 0.00 Russian Cause 0.2 0.0 0.00 Russian Party for the Defense of Women 0.4 0.0 0.00 Social Democrats 0.1 0.0 0.00 Socialist Party of Russia 0.1 0.0 0.00 Stalinist Bloc-for the Soviet Union 0.4 0.0 0.00 Women of Russia 1.4 0.0 0.00 83 Source: Rossiiskaya Gazeta, January 6, 2000 and [Online] http://www.rg.ru 98 substantially under-represented, but received seats in parliament. While Yabloko’s total vote actually increased from 1995 to 1999, it received a less proportional distribution of seats. NDR’s performance declined precipitously and its seat acquisition decreased along with its loss of support in the electorate. Although fewer parties were proportionally represented in the 1999 Duma than in earlier elections, the mechanical effect remained conducive to the participation of marginal parties. As in Lithuania and Russia, Ukraine’s mechanical effect in 1998 did not punish smaller parties to the benefit of large parties (see Table 10).84 The People’s Democratic Party (NDP), Communist Party of Ukraine (KPU), and Greens were over-represented in the Rada. Rukh and Gromada were also over-represented, but less so. Menshe Sliv, the Progressive Socialist Party (PSP) and the Social Democratic Party (United) (SDPU) were under- represented, but only slightly. Nine parties were over-represented or slightly under-represented. In sum, this evidence suggests that the mechanical effect does not provide disincentives for small parties to participate in elections in a mixed system. 8‘ In order to calculate the mechanical effect in Ukraine, parties that were part of an electoral bloc in the PR component were combined with that party. Since a list of all of the parties in a bloc appeared on the PR ballot, the combination of all members into a single party is logical. Thus, the Socialist and Peasant Bloc includes the Socialist Party and Peasant Party. Working Ukraine includes the Ukrainian Party of Justice and the Citizens’ Congress of Ukraine. National Front includes the Ukrainian Republican Party, Ukrainian Conservative Republican Party and Congress of Ukrainian Nationalists. RAZOM includes the Liberal Party and the Party of Rights. Fonivard Ukraine includes the Ukrainian Christian Democratic Party and the Christian Democratic Union. The Bloc of Democratic Parties includes the Democratic Party of Ukraine and the Party of Economic Development. SLON includes the Inter-Regional Bloc of Reform and the Constitutional Democratic Party. Menshe Sliv includes the Social National Party and 99 Table 10: Mechanical Effect for the Mixed System (Ukraine 1998)85 Party % Votes % Seats A People's Democratic Party 4.9 6.3 1.29 Communist Party of Ukraine 20.3 26.1 1.29 Greens 3.4 4.2 1.23 Rukh 8.3 9.6 1.15 Gromada 4.4 4.5 1 .02 Menshe Sliv 0.2 0.2 0.96 Progressive Socialist Party 2.6 2.5 0.95 Social Democratic Party (United) 3.1 2.9 0.92 Socialists and Agrarian Bloc 7.0 6.3 0.90 Party of Regional Development 0.7 0.4 0.61 Agrarian Party of Ukraine 3.7 1.8 0.48 Soyuz 0.5 0.2 0.47 National Front 2.9 1 .1 0.39 Christian-Democratic Party 1.2 0.4 0.38 SLON 0.7 0.2 0.30 Reform and Order 2.6 0.7 0.26 Forward, Ukraine 1.2 0.4 0.18 Block of Democratic Parties 1.3 0.2 0.17 RAZOM 1.7 0.2 0.13 Working Ukraine 2.0 0.2 0.11 All Ukrainian Party of Women's Initiatives 0.4 0.0 0.00 All Ukrainian Workers' Party 0.5 0.0 0.00 European Choice of Ukraine 0.2 0.0 0.00 Party of Defenders of the Homeland 0.2 0.0 0.00 Party of Muslims 0.1 0.0 0.00 Party of National Economic Development 0.5 0.0 0.00 Party of Spiritual, Economic and Social 0.2 0.0 0.00 Progress Republican Christian Party 0.5 0.0 0.00 Social Democratic Party 0.3 0.0 0.00 Ukrainian National Assembly 0.4 0.0 0.00 Government Sovereignty of Ukraine. European Choice of Ukraine includes the Liberal Democratic Party of Ukraine and the Ukrainian Peasants’ Democratic Party. 85 Source: Central Electoral Commission of Ukraine (1998, 236-238). 100 It is important to note that a party receiving a proportional seat allocation may not choose to participate in subsequent elections. For example, Dignity and Charity received a small number of votes, but also a seat, in the Russian Duma that was elected in 1993. However, it disappeared from the political landscape after 1993. Even favorable institutional rules do not prevent financial difficulties, personnel problems or political infighting from dooming parties that perform well in elections. Proportionality Profiles Comparing the proportionality of seat allocation across parties is instructive, but it does not allow us to measure the mechanical effect of the mixed system against the SMD system. Because SMD with plurality rules is less forgiving to small parties than PR, it is important to assess whether or not the mixed system, which contains an SMD component, is more punishing to marginal political parties. Proportionality profiles help make these direct comparisons. By juxtaposing the Advantage Ratio and the percentage of votes received by parties on a figure, we can compare the mechanical effect in mixed systems and SMD systems. While proportionality profiles were first outlined by Laakso and Taagepera (1980), Taagepera and Shugart (1989) describe standard profiles for PR and SMD systems based on cross-national empirical evidence. In a proportionality profile, aggregate data from elections are arrayed on a figure in which the Y axis represents proportionality (the Advantage Ratio) and 101 the X axis represents the proportion of votes received. The perfect proportionality line is a horizontal line that intersects the Y axis at 1.00 (the proportion of seats and the proportion of votes are equal). Every proportionality profile has a break-even point, the point at which the average profile curve intersects the perfect proportionality line. On average, parties accruing a proportion of votes corresponding with the break-even point receive a proportionate allocation of seats in the legislature. Taagepera and Shugart (1989, 70) indicate that SMD systems typically have a Very Late Rise profile in which the proportionality profile gradually rises to a break-even point at approximately 40% on the X axis. The data continue in an upward pattern and plateau at approximately 1.4 on the Y axis. In this pattern, parties that receive a relatively small proportion of the vote tend to be under-represented; parties that receive a moderate or large proportion of the vote tend to be over-represented.86 The underlying question is thus: what is the best fitting functional form for the data produced by mixed electoral systems? If the functional form of mixed systems diverges from the functional form of SMD in a way that is more forgiving to marginal parties, we can conclude that the mechanical effect of mixed systems will encourage small parties to participate in elections. Scatterplot smoothers are well suited to evaluate this hypothesis. With a scatterplot smoother, such as loess, the precise form of the data is not assumed ‘36 It should be noted that comparing actual results to model results from Taagepera and Shugart does not force the systems under analysis to conform to an unrealistic ideal. Rather than representing an ideal, the proportionality profiles are derived from empirical evidence from many countries. 102 to correspond to any particular shape. Rather, the data are used to generate the best-fitting functional form. The test is non-parametric and allows the researcher to conduct bivariate or multivariate analysis. With loess, the smoother calculates the best-fitting line for a portion of the data. This “windovV’ moves along the X-axis and the calculation of the best- fitting line is repeated until the entire form is generated. The researcher can determine the preferred size of this “window,” called the bandwidth (1). There is no preferred bandwidth, although the fit becomes smoother as the bandwidth increases. While there are many different types of scatterplot smoothers, loess is widely employed because it combines some of the best features of smoothers (Hastie and Tibshirani 1990). I applied loess to each of the countries under analysis to generate proportionality profiles using the default bandwidth for individual countries and a 0.75 bandwidth for the combined sample.87 The shape of Lithuania’s proportionality profile, based on loess, diverges from the Very Late Rise profile, typical of SMD systems (see Figure 2).88 There is a single outlier in these results, Homeland Union. This party performed extremely well in the first round of the SMD component, garnering 30% of the total vote. The remaining parties received less than 15% of the vote. The break- even point is substantially lower than SMD because parties receiving a modest proportion of the vote were proportionately represented in the Seimas. Based 87 Independent candidates were omitted from the analysis. 88 The Very Late Rise profile, associated with SMD systems, has been placed on each of the figures and is labeled “Standard SMD.” This profile is an asymptotic result based on cross- national and longitudinal data whereas individual profiles are from single countries. Thus, the comparison of the standard SMD profile to mixed systems constitutes an evaluation of the hypothesis rather than a formal test. 103 % Seats/% Votes 3.0 2.5 ‘ N C 1 1.5— .5 o l 0.5 ‘ 0.0 ‘ Lithuania Standard SMD —r 0 Figure 2: Proportionality Profile for Lithuania 104 60 on Lithuanian data, it appears that marginal parties can receive a proportional allocation of seats in a mixed system. This should encourage small parties to continue to participate in elections. The Lithuanian results must be interpreted with care, however. The SMD component of Lithuania’s mixed system is based on a majority-runoff system not a plurality system like other mixed systems in the analysis. Although final seat distributions were used to calculate disproportionality, votes are based only on the first round.89 Russia’s mixed system proportionality profiles also diverge from the standard SMD profile. Based on the loess analysis, data from the 1993 Russran Duma elections appear to more closely approximate the pr0portionality profile of PR systems rather than SMD systems (see Figure 3). The proportionality profile rises quickly and then follows the perfect proportionality line as values increase along the X axis. Like the Flat or Early Rise profiles (Taagepera and Shugart 1 989 70) that are typically associated with PR, the proportionality prof le for Russia 3 1993 elections shows that parties receiving a relatively small pr0portion of the vote are proportionally represented in the Duma. These results diverge from SMD and promote multiparty competition. Russia’s proportionality profile for 1995 also diverges from the Very Late Rise profile (see Figure 4). Unlike the 1993 profile that followed the perfect proportionality line, the profile in 1995 is close to a straight line. These results \ L"il‘luania’ 5 use of a majority-runoff ballot for SMD complicates the proportionality profile 89 paalcuiation. Many seats were not allocated until the second round, but most parties did not rt"lipate in runoff elections. Thus, I use vote outcomes from the first round and seat allocation 105 are due in large part to the disproportionate results in PR. Because only four parties passed the threshold in the PR component and these parties divided all 225 seats among themselves, they were over-represented in the Duma. Although there are differences between Russia’s 1993 and 1995 profiles, neither approximates the SMD profile. Parties receiving a relatively small proportion of the vote are able to gain a proportionate seat allocation. The 1999 proportionality profile has an unusual shape but is similar to the 1 993 profile (see Figure 5). The profile has a large trough between 0 and 10 on the X axis. This is due to the loess default bandwidth and distribution of the data points. Despite the unusual shape, the break-even point for the profile is far lower than the break-even point for the SMD system. Moreover, the profile fol lows the perfect proportionality line as the values increase along the X axis. Once again, the profile is shaped more like a PR proportionality profile than S M D. Ukraine’s proportionality profile is similar to the shape of the 1993 and 1 999 Russian profiles (see Figure 6). The break-even point is lower than in SMD and many parties garnering a small proportion of the votes received a pr Oportionate distribution of legislative seats. The proportionality profile for Ukraine diverges from Russia in that it plateaus at a higher value along the Y axis- Nevertheless, it is more forgiving to small parties than the standard SMD VeW Late Rise profile. \ fr thoe' ' | the second round. In this way, I capture the votes received by all parties in the election and aCtual seat distribution. 106 % Seats/% Votes 3.0 2.5 " .N O 1 1.5“ A C l .0 on r 0.0 ‘ Standard SMD Russia 93 ' ' o O O T T l l l l 0 1 O 20 30 4O 50 60 % Votes Figure 3: Proportionality Profile for Russia (1993) 107 % Seats/% Votes 3.0 2.5 N o 1.5 .A O 0.5 0.0 Russia 95 0 Standard SMD 1 0 20 30 40 50 % Votes Figure 4: Proportionality Profile for Russia (1995) 108 60 %Seats/% Votes 3.0 2.5 T 2.0 T Standard SMD 1.5 -< Russia 99 /\:y/0 1.0 T o o O O O 0.5 T 0.0 T I l I I T T 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 % Votes Figure 5: Proportionality Profile for Russia (1999) 109 % Seats/%Votes 3.0 2.5 T 2.0 T 1.5T 1.0T 0.5 T 0.0 T Ukraine Standard SMD 20 30 40 % Votes 50 Figure 6: Proportionality Profile for Ukraine (1998) 110 60 All of the mixed systems analyzed here seem to differ from the Very Late Rise profile identified by Taagepera and Shugart. Pooling the data from all five elections provides a picture of the mechanical effect in mixed systems. Before combining the data, I conducted a modified Chow Test for structural stability. The test assesses if the intercept or slope of the individual cases differ substantially from one another. If there is no structural change, the samples can be combined (Gujarati 1995). The test is: S /2 n,- - 2k where S1 is the Residual Sum of Squares (RSS) of the pooled data less the RSS of the cross sections summed, 82 is the RSS of the cross sections summed, k is the number of regressors, and in; is the number of cross sections. The null hypothesis is that the cross sections can be combined (there is structural stability). The calculated F statistic is 2.7; the critical F“ ,3) at 95% confidence is 10.1. The null hypothesis cannot be rejected and the cross sections can be pooled. Figure 7 provides a proportionality profile for all of the previous elections and compares it to the standard SMD profile. Like the individual proportionality profiles, the combined profile has a break-even point that is lower than that of a standard SMD system. There is a sizable cluster of slightly over-represented parties and slightly under-represented parties between 0 and 20 on the X axis. This suggests that parties receiving low to moderate support in the electorate 111 % Seats/% Votes 3.0 2.5 ‘ 2 0 _ Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine Standard SMD 1.5 - 1.0 ~ 0.5 ~ 0.0 ‘ T l I l l l o 10 20 so 40 so so % Votes Figure 7: Proportionality Profile for Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine 112 % Seats/%Votes N‘ “\I’ m I III II IIIII IIIIIHIIIHHHIIW iI sand,” SMD "' ‘ I” I I 'II III III II' II I II III II III II. 'II * /\ o I" ‘ w ‘_' Tl ll % Votes Figure 8: Proportionality Profile for Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine with 95% Confidence Intervals 113 can indeed receive a proportionate seat allocation in mixed electoral systems. Whereas the mechanical effect in SMD systems punishes small parties by favoring parties that receive 40% or more of the vote, the mechanical effect in mixed systems facilitates representation by marginal parties. This should encourage small parties to participate in future elections. Figure 8 applies 95% confidence intervals to the combined proportionality profile and shows that the profile diverges from the Very Late Rise profile with a high level of confidence. Proportionality profiles from other mixed systems further support the notion that the mechanical effect in mixed electoral systems is more forgiving than the mechanical effect in SMD systems. Results from Japan, New Zealand, Scotland and Wales are quite similar to those found in Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine (see Appendix B). Not only do these states have more institutionalized party systems, but three of them use compensatory rules that link PR and SMD seat acquisition. This suggests that the more forgiving mechanical effect in mixed systems is not attenuated by institutional variation within mixed systems. Conclusions In sum, there is strong evidence supporting the Mechanical Effect Hypothesis. Many parties in Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine were over- represented or slightly under-represented in the elections under analysis. While the mechanical effect “filtered out” some small parties, many marginal parties gained proportionate representation in the legislature. 114 The proportionality profiles for each election further illustrated that the mechanical effect encourages small parties to participate in elections. When they were compared to the standard mechanical effect in SMD systems, the break-even points were lower and the shape of the profile differed. The profiles for the mixed systems were similar to those associated with PR, moreover, suggesting that the incentives produced by the system may be similar to those generated in PR. The effect on party strategy should be clear. Although the mixed system contains an element of SMD, this component, in concert with PR, does not create the same incentive structure as a standard SMD system. If small parties are not excluded from legislative representation due to the mechanical effect, it is less likely that they will drop from competition. As voters recognize that small parties can win seats in parliament, they are more likely to vote sincerely. As contributors recognize that small parties can play an active role in government, they are less likely to pull away resources. As candidates see that small parties are viable engines for access to legislative positions, they are less likely to abandon them for larger parties. In short, the less punishing mechanical effect creates an environment that encourages multipartism. 115 Chapter 4 THE INVESTMENT EFFECT The evaluation of the mechanical effect demonstrated that small parties are likely to participate in mixed electoral systems because the mechanical effect is more forgiving than SMD’s mechanical effect. The general tendency should be for many parties to commit to competition in elections under mixed rules. The next question is: how will parties choose to participate in the system? Theoretically, a party could sponsor candidates in SMD but not register in PR. However, parties that do not register in PR are generally accorded different access to campaign finance and media access than those on the PR ballot. In Lithuania’s 1996 Seimas elections, a registered party was allowed to spend twenty times as much as an individual candidate on election activities (Election Law 2000).90 Because the party’s spending limits were for the national list, a candidate could benefit from the party’s national campaign and still mount an individual campaign in the district, subject to the restrictions for candidates. An unregistered party would not be permitted to spend the additional funds restricted to party lists. Registered parties also received additional benefits in advertising. While all candidates and parties were allocated free advertising, parties received one and one-half hours of national television and radio time. Individual candidates 9° Law on Elections to the Seimas, Section VII, Article 54. 116 were aiio Once age party’s ad ln l registered both on th organizatii Candidate: Individuals COUId rece individuals Could also IImes the r times the r adVemSms OnI RUSSIa'S 1 equal mm addmofiaj were allotted five minutes of television time and seven minutes of radio time.91 Once again, candidates affiliated with registered parties could benefit from the party’s additional free air time. In Russia’s 1999 elections, campaign finance regulations also favored registered political parties over unregistered parties. Limitations were placed both on the amount of money that could be received from individuals and organizations as well as a maximum amount that could be spent.92 Individual candidates could receive donations 100 times the minimum wage from individuals and 2,000 times the minimum wage from organizations. Parties could receive substantially larger donations — 150 times the minimum wage from individuals and 20,000 times the minimum wage from organizations. Parties could also spend far more than candidates. The limit for parties was 250,000 times the minimum wage while candidates could spend no more than 10,000 times the minimum wage (IF ES 1999).93 Affiliated candidates benefit from party advertising and from both national and individual fundraising. Only registered parties received free time on national stations94 in Russia’s 1999 elections. Television and radio stations were required to provide equal time to competing candidates/parties. Regional party lists were allocated additional local air time. The amount of time given to SMD candidates was multiplied by the number of districts in the region to determine how much free 9’ Law on Elections to the Seimas, Section VII, Article 51. 92 While limitations on the collection and expenditure of funds existed in practice in the 1999 campaign, conversations with two candidates (who requested anonymity) suggest that these regulations were widely violated. 93 Law on the Election of Deputies of the State Duma of the Federal Assembly of the Russian Federation, Chapter IX, Article 62. These are networks with a clear signal to more than half of the residents of Russia. 117 time region with a part) PR Iist’s i0 unregisteri process f0 television WI in Ukraine Specify lir of free teI Candidati SeDarate tI’Iéiri ind. parties 2 1999);? advahte time regional party lists received?"5 Thus, a candidate in an SMD race affiliated with a party could benefit from the party’s national advertisements, the regional PR list’s local advertisements, and his own time. Candidates affiliated with unregistered parties could only use the time allocated to candidates. The process for allocating free space in the print media was similar to radio and television (IFES 1999).96 While the law is ambiguous about campaign finance and advertisements in Ukraine, it seems to provide benefits to registered parties. The law does not specify limitations on campaign finance, nor does it specify the minimum amount of free television or radio advertising. The law, however, separates parties and candidates when it outlines campaign finance, implying that they are treated separately. Registered parties are allocated more free space in the print media than individual candidates to publish their platforms, suggesting that registered parties are likely to receive benefits not accorded to unregistered parties (NAU 1999).97 Thus, it is logical for political parties to register in PR in order to take advantage of the additional benefits accorded to parties that participate in PR. Just as a party could sponsor candidates in SMD alone, it could also participate solely in PR. If parties aim to maximize the number of legislative seats in parliament, this approach is not logical. Parties must make a substantial investment of resources to mount a campaign in the PR component of the elections. By committing to a national PR race, the party leadership is 95 Law on the Election of Deputies of the State Duma of the Federal Assembly of the Russian Federation, Chapter VIII, Article 56. 96 Law on the Election of Deputies of the State Duma of the Federal Assembly of the Russian Federation, Chapter VIII, Article 57. 118 presumat fill its par commits t mSMDs candidate not be prI Party imp Candidate Tr Participa is so! pa! faces, Ir inlly in S PaniClp; presumably confident that it has an adequate number of qualified politicians to fill its party list and enough resources to advertise. Once the organization commits to the national PR race, the marginal cost of running some candidates in SMD should be low. Parties may not have adequate resources to sponsor candidates in all SMD races, but the cost of participating in some races should not be prohibitive. Furthermore, by taking part in SMD races as well as PR, the party improves the odds of gaining legislative seats simply by fielding candidates in more races. The Investment Effect indicates that the decision of parties to participate in PR will encourage some level of participation in SMD. If this is so, parties participating in PR should place multiple candidates in SMD races. In addition, parties with greater resources should participate more fully in SMD than those with fewer resources. Participation in PR and SMD Table 11 shows the level of SMD participation for parties that registered in PR during Russia’s 1993, 1995 and 1999 elections.” All thirteen parties in 1993 placed candidates in SMD. The Women of Russia party placed the fewest SMD candidates (6) and Russia’s Choice placed the most (110). The pattern is the same in 1995. All parties participating in PR placed at least two SMD 97 Law on the Election of Deputies to the Verkhovna Rada, Chapter 5, Article 34. 98 There were 225 districts in all three elections. 119 Table 11 PartI 'iWss Russ Agra Civic YablI Pan) Dem Russ Liber ComI Futur Kedr Digni Worr Our t Cong Forw COmI BlOc POwe UDlOI Pamt SOCIE Pan) Bldg 09': My F RUSS BIQC Stab A830 Pan) P80: Tran: D . % SOUrQe. BJOSSIIska' Ger ‘1' mOCr-at. The LDPRIC Table 11: SMD Participation by Parties Registered in PR (Russia 1993, 1995 and 1999) Party # of SMD Candidates 1993 1995 1999 Russia’s Choice/Democratic Choice of 110 72 - Russia100 Agrarian Party of Russia 74 87 - Civic Union 73 - - Yabloko 69 69 116 Party of Russian Unity and Accord 69 23 - Democratic Party of Russia 62 - - Russian Movement for Democratic Reforms 60 - - Liberal-Democratic Party of Russia101 58 184 92 Communist Party of the Russian Federation 57 130 130 Future of Russia-New Names 36 - - Kedr 23 19 - Dignity and Charity 11 - - Women of Russia 6 20 12 Our Home is Russia - 103 92 Congress of Russian Communities - 90 45 Forward, Russia! - 67 - Communists-Workers of Russia-for the USSR - 64 18 Bloc of Ivan Rybkin - 64 - Power to the People! - 41 - Union of Labor - 40 - Pamfilova-Gurov-Lysenko - 33 - Social Democrats - 29 Party of Worker Self-Government - 27 - Bloc of Stanislav Govorukhin - 25 - Derzhava - 25 - My Fatherland - 18 - Russian All-National Movement - 18 - Bloc of Independents - 17 - Stable Russia - 17 - Association of Russian Attorneys - 15 - Party of Economic Freedom - 15 - People's Union - 15 - Transformation of the Fatherland - 15 - Duma-96 - 14 - 99 Source: Central Electoral Commission of the Russian Federation (1995; 1996; 2000); Rossiiskaya Gazeta (1996; 2000). 10° Democratic Choice of Russia (DVR) was the successor party to Russia’s Choice in 1995. ‘0’ The LDPR ran as the Zhirinovskiy Bloc in 1999 due to problems with registration. 120 Table 11 (cont’d) Christian-Democratic Union Beer Lovers' Party Federal-Democratic Movement For the Motherland! lnterethnic Union Union of Housing Construction Workers Generation of the Frontier Tikhonov-Tupolev-Tikhonov Bloc of Dzhuna National-Republican Party of Russia Spiritual Heritage Fatherland - All Russia Bloc of Andrei Nikolayev and Svyatoslav Fyodorov Union of Right Forces Russian Socialist Party Medved Party of Pensioners Russian National Union Movement in Support of the Army For Citizens’ Dignity Russian Cause Stalinist Bloc - for the Soviet Union Socialist Party of Russia Party of Peace and Unity All-Russian Party of the People Conservative Party of Russia Russian Party for the Defense of Women 13 11 11 imcootcnouoj JAN coo-souxtowo 121 Table 12 : Party FIE Rept Lithu Lithu Hom Lithu Lithu Litht New Litht Litht Litht Dep Litht Lithi Lith Chr Lith The Lit!" Litt Litt Th Liti Lit \ //7 Table 12: SMD Participation by Parties Registered in PR (Lithuania 1996)102 Party # of SMD Candidates Lithuanian Social Democratic Party 71 Republican Party 68 Lithuanian Democratic Labor Party 67 Lithuanian Christian Democratic Party 67 Homeland Union - Lithuanian Conservatives 67 Lithuanian Centre Union 53 Lithuanian National Union 52 Lithuanian Party of Economy 45 New DemocracyNVomen's Party 44 Lithuanian Liberal Union 35 Lithuanian Peasants' Party 34 Lithuanian Union of Political Prisoners and 33 Deportees Lithuanian Poles’ Electoral Action 22 Lithuanian Party of Life's Logic 22 Lithuanian Socialist Party 20 Christian Democratic Union 17 Lithuanian National Party "Young Lithuania" 16 The Party of National Progress 15 Lithuanian Union of Social Justice 11 Lithuanian People's Party 11 Lithuanian Freedom League 11 The Union of the Russians of Lithuania 10 Lithuanian Citizens' Alliance 10 Lithuanian Freedom Union 9 ‘02 Source: Electoral Commission of Lithuania (1999). 122 Table 13: Party Rukr Gron Com- Natic Soci: Soci; RAZ Gree PeOI Bloc Agra Refc Prot Chri EUl’l For Table 13: SMD Participation by Parties Registered in PR (Ukraine 1998)103 Party # of SMD Candidates’o" Rukh 186 Gromada 181 Communist Party of Ukraine 174 National Front 164 Socialist and Agrarian Bloc 129 Social Democratic Party (United) 128 RAZOM 1 16 Greens 1 15 People’s Democratic Party 108 Bloc of Democratic Parties 103 Agrarian Party of Ukraine 85 Reform and Order 83 Progressive Socialist Party 74 Christian Democratic Party 66 European Choice of Ukraine 59 Forward, Ukraine 53 Ukrainian National Assembly 52 Republican Christian Party 49 Working Ukraine 48 Social-Democratic Party 42 Party of Regional Development 42 All Ukrainian Workers’ Party 40 SLON 37 Party of the Defenders of the Homeland 29 Menshe Sliv 23 Party of Spiritual, Economic and Social 18 Progress Soyuz 12 Party of Muslims 11 Party of National Economic Development 10 All Ukrainian Party of Women’s Initiatives 5 ‘03 Source: Central Electoral Commission of Ukraine (1998). 1°“ The measure includes candidates from related parties that were a part of the electoral bloc and those who were sponsored by the party. The variable SMDPL is calculated in a slightly different manner, reflecting the peculiarities of the Ukrainian ballot. Therefore, the number of SMD candidates on this table and in the later analysis differ slightly. I include party sponsorship, rather than membership, because the question I evaluate here is how parties nominate candidates in SMD. Because they control sponsorship and indirectly control how members will behave, sponsorship is the better measure here. In other analyses, however, membership is more important because it is the factor that appears on the ballot. 123 candida candida (184). ( placed t T 1996 ca thuani Party‘s '. Women Rukh s; Particip; F typical“ mixed 5 SMD, as Daniel; 8830C“ perpet, The E I a / l l ’l ( Tm hi candidates. The National-Republican Party fielded the lowest number of SMD candidates (2) and the Liberal Democratic Party of Russia placed the most (184). Of the 26 parties in 1999, three fielded no SMD candidates; the KPRF placed the most SMD candidates (130). The pattern is repeated in other states. All political parties in Lithuania’s 1996 campaign sponsored multiple SMD candidates, ranging from the Lithuanian Freedom League’s 9 candidates to the Lithuanian Social Democratic Party’s 71 candidates (see Table 12).105 In Ukraine, the All-Ukrainian Party of Women’s Initiatives placed the fewest SMD candidates (5) (see Table 13). Rukh sponsored the largest SMD contingent (186).106 Once again, all parties participating in PR also ran candidates in SMD. Parties participating in the PR component of mixed systems have typically fielded multiple SMD candidates. Because the mechanical effect of mixed systems is not as punishing to small parties as the mechanical effect in SMD, as established in Chapter 3, marginal parties should continue to participate in elections. Committing to competition in PR seems to be associated with placing multiple SMD candidates, a tendency that should perpetuate multipartism. The Effect of Resources on Participation While the empirical pattern of participation in both components of the mixed system is clear, what factors lead some parties to participate in just a few 105 There were 71 SMD districts in Lithuania's 1996 elections. ‘06 There were 225 SMD districts in Ukraine’s 1998 elections. 124 districts suggest SMD rac assertIOI election: T has plac measure P€fsonn Paris/’8 t eqUIpDE grassro ShOuld PREVE Parties SITU ctu districts and others to run many candidates in SMD? The Investment Effect suggests that the ability to overcome the marginal costs of placing candidates in SMD races should, in part, influence how fully a party participates in SMD. This assertion can be evaluated with data from the most recent parliamentary elections in Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine. The dependent variable is the proportion of SMD districts in which a party has placed candidates.‘°7 Three independent variables represent different measures of a party’s resources. The variable PRLIST assesses the party’s personnel resources by measuring the proportion of PR seats covered by the party’s PR list. A party with greater personnel resources should be better equipped to overcome the costs of SMD participation. PRVOTE measures grassroots support for the party. A party with greater support in the electorate should receive more financial support from the population. The dummy variable PREVELECT represents parties that participated in the previous election. Parties with a longer electoral history presumably have a stronger organizational structure and a greater resource base. The results of the OLS analysis in Table 14 show that a party’s ability to overcome the costs of SMD participation should also affect its level of participation in the SMD component of the mixed system (see the column labeled Model 1). The coefficients for PRLIST and PREVELECT are statistically significant and positive in sign. This indicates that parties with greater personnel resources are likely to field a larger contingent of SMD candidates than those ‘07 For Ukraine, this is the proportion of districts in which candidates were sponsored by the party, regardless of a candidate’s party membership. 125 Table 14: Effect of Resources on SMD Placement Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Variable ,6 and SE g and SE ,6 and SE Constant -4.434 -62.016*** -.619 (4.013) (13.598) (6.542) ,6, PR List 512*“ 374* (067) (198) ,6; PR Vote .453 1.048** .368 (.407) (.413) (.424) ,6; Previous Election 8.783“ 9.246“ 8.509” (4.404) (4.818) (4.434) ,64 Logged PR List 22.147*** (3.603) ,6; Squared PR List .001 (.001) Adjusted R2 .641 .571 .639 N 72 72 72 Dependent Variable: Proportion of SMD races in which candidates were placed. Standard errors are in parentheses. Note: All parties participating in the most recent elections in Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine were included in the analysis. Some parties in Lithuania did not submit PR lists and were excluded. * ps.10 ** ps.05 *** ps.01 126 with few shows tl candida affect S! is not sta existing N PRLIST SMD mg a loQgec T (see Ta. Ihe .05 I HOWSVE Indicate mOre Ct l and PF MOreQ. Table by ad; reIaiic with fewer personnel resources. The statistical significance of PREVELECT shows that parties that are more established in society nominate more candidates in SMD. The resources associated with stronger party organization affect SMD placement strategies. The coefficient evaluating grassroots support is not statistically significant, indicating that this is less important than the party’s existing resources when determining how fully the party will participate in SMD. Models 2 and 3 evaluate a potential non-linear relationship between PRLIST and SMDPER. As party personnel resources increase, placement in SMD may not increase at the same rate. To control for this possibility, I include a logged version of PRLIST in Model 2 and squared PRLIST in Model 3. The natural log of PRLIST is statistically significant and positive in sign (see Table 14, Model 2). In addition, the coefficient for PRVOTE is significant at the .05 level and PREVELECT is significant at the .10 level in Model 2. However, based on adjusted R2, Model 2’s overall fit is lower than Model 1. This indicates that despite the significance of logged PRLIST, Model 1 presents a more complete picture of the effect of resources on candidate placement. While the inclusion of squared PRLIST mitigates the effects of PRLIST and PREVELECT in Model 3, the coefficients remain significant at the .10 level. Moreover, the parameter of squared PRLIST is not statistically significant (see Table 14, Model 3). The fit of Model 3 is also lower than Model 1, as measured by adjusted R2. Thus, the linear approach seems to best capture the relationship between resources and SMD placement. 127 A function: may be c 12 and 1 proportic it is impc M While Pl Russia c reflects I Although Models 2 and 3 do not undermine confidence in the linear functional form, Model 1 does not fully control for other possible effects. There may be country-specific factors that influence candidate placement. Tables 11, 12 and 13 show that major parties in Russia, on average, participate in a smaller proportion of SMD races than their counterparts in Ukraine and Lithuania. Thus, it is important to add controls for these influences. Model 4 includes country dummy variables for Russia and Ukraine. While PRLIST and PREVELECT remain significant and positive in sign, the Russia country dummy is significant and negative (see Table 15, Model 4). This reflects the lower level of SMD participation found among Russian parties. Model 5 adds interactive variables for PRLIST and the country dummies. The fit of this model improves over previous models, with an adjusted R2 of .81. While PRLIST and PREVELECT persist as significant predictors of SMD placement, RUSSlA*PRLlST is significant and negative in sign (see Table 15, Model 5). The total effect of PRLlST is thus lower in Russia than its coefficient suggests. The PRLIST coefficient value of .575 is attenuated by the -.291 coefficient of RUSSIA*PRL|ST, generating a total effect of .283 for Russia. The total effect remains significant and positive, indicating that greater personnel resources lead to fuller participation in SMD for all three countries. Even when controls are added for country-specific factors, the effects of personnel resources and organizational capacity remain. 128 Table ‘ De St anda time. . and UI and We 1” Table 15: Effect of Resources on SMD Placement (Fixed Effects Models) Model 4 Model 5 Variable ,8 and SE ,6 and SE Constant 1 .945 -3.648 (5.380) (6.641) [3, PR List .511*** .575*** (.056) (.074) pg PR Vote .453 .457 (.327) (.306) ,6; Previous Election 8.895“ 9250*“ (3.708) (3.457) ,84 Russia -19.474*** -.021 (4.341) (8.306) ,6; Ukraine 1.612 .905 (4.499) (7.863) ,66 Russia *PR List -.292*** (.102) [37 Ukraine *PR List .054 (.099) Adjusted R2 .775 .805 N 72 72 Dependent Variable: Proportion of SMD races in which candidates were placed. Standard errors are in parentheses. Note: All parties participating in the most recent elections in Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine were included. Some parties in Lithuania did not submit PR lists and were excluded. Lithuania is the excluded case in Models 4 and 5. * ps.10 ** p305 *** ps.01 129 Altema L Many fa margins and are well- knt this is St party's a determir E explanai mixed 5) that part SDODSQr ”Wasn( wefind: Alternate Explanations for SMD Placement Large and small parties tend to participate fully in the mixed system. Many factors could motivate this behavior, not only a party’s resources. Some marginal parties may place candidates in districts where they enjoy local support and are likely to win the seat. Alternatively, they could have a contingent of well- known local personalities who are strong contenders for the district seat. If this is so, resources alone would not dictate placement strategies in SMD. The party’s assessment of its likelihood of winning the seat could play a role in determining where it sponsors local SMD candidates. Examples from Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine suggest that this alternate explanation does not account for parties’ tendencies to participate fully in the mixed system. If we examine the performance of candidates in SMD by parties that participated in fewer than ten SMD races, we find that parties did not tend to sponsor highly competitive candidates and they did not tend to focus placement on a single region. In addition, if we select a moderate party from each country, we find similar results.108 In Russia’s 1999 Duma elections, three small parties placed more than one candidate, but fewer than ten candidates, in SMD (see Table 16). The Social Democrats (SD) had five affiliated candidates in SMD. The candidates were not concentrated in a single geographic constituency, suggesting that the party does not enjoy support in a specific location. The best-performing candidate received 2.4% of the local vote and finished in ninth place. Thus, it 130 does m were lik better ir E (SPR) rt perform; were no receive: Party do district, ) received Tl fOUnd w, Candldat the vote. Camdidat ability to I01163! PR K KTR als< organiza N ‘ Set 4 .e faneq to :1) does not seem likely that the party sponsored candidates in SMD that it thought were likely winners in the districts. In three of five districts, the party performed better in the local PR vote than at the national level. Each candidate participating in SMD for the Socialist Party of Russia (SPR) received a proportion of the vote exceeding the party’s aggregate PR performance. Nevertheless, none of the candidates were competitive and they were not placed in a single geographic area. The most successful candidate received 3.1% of the local vote and finished sixth in the district. Once again, this party does not seem to have placed likely winners in the districts. In each district, however, the party received a higher proportion of the PR vote than it received in the aggregate. The Stalinist Bloc — for the Soviet Union (STAL) repeated the pattern found with the Social Democrats and Socialist Party of Russia. The top candidate for this party finished in third place in his district, receiving 8.41% of the vote. While this candidate was a potential competitor, the remaining candidates were not. Candidate placement does not seem to be based on the ability to win a district race. in all but one case, the party performed better in the local PR race than it did at the national level. KTR is an example of a medium-sized party in Russia’s 1999 elections. KT R also participated in 1995, showing that it should have greater organizational capacity than the small parties in the analysis. However, it failed to pass the threshold in both 1995 and 1999. Table 17 shows the relative ‘08 I selected a moderate party for each country that participated in the previous election, but failed to cross the threshold by the smallest margin. Because very small parties may not be 131 Table 16: Performance of Small Parties (Russia 1999)‘°° Party District % Vote Candidate % Vote % Vote PR SMo"° Finished’" PR (Local) aggregate) so 104 0.82 10 (16) 0.09 0.08 so 173 1.38 13 (18) 0.08 0.08 so 193 0.53 11 (11) 0.07 0.08 so 197 2.38 9 (12) 0.12 0.08 so 211 0.60 9 (9) 0.09 0.08 SPR 18 0.55 10 (14) 0.17 0.09 SPR 39 1.07 7 (8) 0.11 0.09 SPR 52 2.71 10 (15) 0.16 0.09 SPR 99 0.52 15 (17) 0.11 0.09 SPR 110 3.09 6 (19) 0.15 0.09 SPR 184 1.84 7 (10) 0.12 0.09 STAL 33 3.42 5 (10) 1.34 0.61 STAL 100 1.86 10 (20) 0.86 0.61 STAL 106 1.64 9 (11) 0.98 0.61 STAL 108 0.83 16 (17) 0.52 0.61 STAL 149 2.13 11 (16) 0.97 0.61 STAL 156 8.41 3 (6) 1.42 0.61 STAL 176 1.64 9 (13) 0.91 0.61 serious political parties, including a moderate party increases confidence in the results. “’9 Source: Rossiiskaya Gazeta (2000). 11° Includes “against all.” "1 The value in parentheses is the number of candidates in the given district. 132 Table 17: Performance of KTR (Russia 1999) Party District % Vote Candidate % Vote % Vote PR SMD112 Finished” PR (Local) (Aggregate) KTR 7 8.69 4 (5) 1.97 2.22 KTR 28 6.12 5 (13) 2.27 2.22 KTR 66 3.14 9 (14) 1.96 2.22 KTR 92 2.79 6 (13) 2.32 2.22 KTR 108 6.03 7 (17) 1.58 2.22 KTR 118 1.60 9 (10) 3.13 2.22 KTR 119 1.00 11 (12) 3.29 2.22 KTR 120 1.52 9 (12) 2.61 2.22 KTR 126 1.15 10 (16) 2.50 2.22 KTR 132 2.47 9 (13) 3.35 2.22 KTR 156 4.34 6 (6) 3.02 2.22 KTR 159 2.61 7 (9) 3.58 2.22 KTR 166 10.51 4 (10) 2.85 2.22 KTR 173 4.78 6 (18) 2.55 2.22 KTR 178 20.69 2 (7) 12.25 2.22 KT R 194 2.02 8 (13) 0.76 2.22 KTR 212 9.89 4 (14) 1.78 2.22 KTR 213 2.69 7 (13) 1.37 2.22 "2 Includes “against all.” "3 The value in parentheses is the number of candidates in the given district. 133 perform parties. vote. OI in their c finished party aIs performa Party W LFU LFU LFU LFU LFU LFU LFU \ Tr Freedom N009 Of . receide With 240A performance of KTR’s candidates in eighteen districts. As with the small parties, KTR tends to perform better in the SMD vote than in the aggregate PR vote. Only five of eighteen candidates accrued a smaller proportion of the vote in their districts than the party gained at the national level. The best candidate finished in second place, but many KT R candidates were not competitive. The party also tended to perform better locally than nationally. The party’s local PR performance outstripped its national PR performance in twelve districts. Table 18: Performance of the LFU (Lithuania 1996)114 Party District % Vote Candidate % Vote % Vote PR SMD Finished115 PR (Local) (Aggregate) LFU 11 7.68 5 (15) 8.08 1.49 LFU 12 24.44 2 (12) 10.78 1.49 LFU 13 5.00 6 (13) 6.01 1.49 LFU 14 6.31 5 (16) 5.96 1.49 LFU 16 6.24 4 (16) 6.87 1.49 LFU 17 6.90 5 (13) 6.95 1.49 LFU 65 2.73 11 (12) 2.51 1.49 LFU 66 3.38 7 (10) 3.19 1.49 This pattern is not limited to Russia. In Lithuania, the Lithuanian Freedom Union (LFU) placed nine candidates in SMD races (see Table 18). None of the candidates received a lower proportion of the vote than the party received in the aggregate. In one district, the candidate finished in second place with 24% of the vote, allowing him to move to the second round. He did not win the seat, however, leaving the LFU with no seats in the Seimas. "4 Source: Electoral Commission of Lithuania (1999). "5 The value in parentheses is the number of candidates in the given district. 134 The Va Table 19: Performance of YL (Lithuania 1996) Party District % Vote Candidate % Vote % Vote PR SMD Finished” PR (Local) (Aggregate) YL 5 3.54 9 (16) 2.77 3.81 YL 7 2.51 8 (16) 2.17 3.81 YL 11 8.64 2 (15) 7.32 3.81 YL 15 23.45 2 (11) 9.83 3.81 YL 16 8.24 3 (16) 7.43 3.81 YL 17 9.44 3 (13) 7.72 3.81 YL 18 5.81 6 (15) 6.78 3.81 YL 22 8.02 5 (11) 4.47 3.81 YL 28 3.33 10 (15) 4.17 3.81 YL 29 3.06 8 (12) 3.90 3.81 YL 41 4.34 7 (12) 6.18 3.81 YL 45 6.22 5 (15) 7.30 3.81 YL 59 4.10 7 (15) 4.87 3.81 YL 60 5.72 8 (13) 5.63 3.81 YL 65 7.17 6 (12) 6.32 3.81 YL 66 9.36 2 (10) 7.74 3.81 135 ”6 The value in parentheses is the number of candidates in the given district. in any c SMD be candida 11-18 a that the Russia. nanonal L Lfihuan) Table 1: party at one was in the di: Well in p the 'OCal TI Cartdidat recewed performs all hot Or fifteen Ca Deny did With this exception, the LFU did not place highly competitive candidates in any of the district races, suggesting that it did not solely sponsor candidates in SMD because it thought the candidates would be competitive. All of the candidates were concentrated in a single geographic area, however. Districts 11-18 are in the city of Kaunas; 65 and 66 surround Kaunas. Thus, it seems that the party placed SMD candidates with the region in mind. Just as in Russia, the party received a higher proportion of the local PR vote than the national PR vote. Lithuania’s moderately sized party, the Lithuanian National Party “Young Lithuania” (YL) continues the pattern that is found with the small parties (see Table 19). In twelve of sixteen districts, the candidate performed better than the party at the national level. Three candidates finished in second place, but only one was victorious in the second round. YL placed some competitive candidates in the districts, but most were not likely to win seats. The party also performed well in PR in districts where it nominated SMD candidates. In fourteen districts, the local PR vote was greater than the party’s national PR vote. The All-Ukrainian Party of Women’s Initiatives (WOM) also sponsored candidates that received a higher local proportion of the vote than the party received in the aggregate, but it did not win any seats (see Table 20). The party performed better in the PR race at the local level than it did in the aggregate in all but one case. The best performing candidate finished third in a district with fifteen candidates. As with other small parties in Russia and Lithuania, this party did not place candidates that were highly competitive in the districts. 136 Table 20: Performance of WOM (Ukraine 1998)117 Party District % Vote Candidate % Vote % Vote PR SMD"8 Finishedm PR (Local) (Aggrgqate) WOM 29 6.40 6(18) 1.18 0.58 WOM 42 1.24 10(20) 0.66 0.58 WOM 46 0.73 15(18) 0.66 0.58 WOM 47 5.92 3(15) 0.92 0.58 WOM 117 0.92 11(21) 0.38 0.58 Three of the five candidates ran in Donetsk Oblast, however, suggesting that regional connections or resources may guide placement decisions. The Christian Democratic Party of Ukraine (CDP) had many SMD candidates on the ballot. In 39 of 69 districts, the candidate performed as well as or better than the party at the national level. The competitiveness of GDP candidates varied widely. While two candidates won their races, there were also many non-competitive candidates. The party performed better in PR at the local level than at the national level in 39 districts. Although local candidate and PR performance exceeded national performance in the same number of districts, the districts did not always correspond. While the relationship between local and national performance is less consistent for the CDP than all previous parties, the patterns generally persist — parties tend to perform better at the local level where SMD candidates appear on the ballot. Marginal parties and the medium sized parties in all three countries did not tend to place highly competitive candidates in district races, undermining the assertion that candidate placement strategies of marginal parties focus primarily "7 Source: Central Electoral Commission of Ukraine (1998). "8 Includes “against all.” 137 Table 21: Performance of the CDP (Ukraine 1998)‘2° Party District % Vote Candidate % Vote % Vote PR SMDm Finished122 PR (Local) (Aggregate) CDP 1 0.82 15 (22) 0.43 1.30 CDP 2 1.36 10 (14) 0.40 1.30 CDP 3 0.68 12 (15) 0.36 1.30 CDP 4 1.73 8 (16) 0.52 1.30 CDP 5 0.66 11 (11) 0.80 1.30 CDP 6 0.72 14 (16) 0.66 1.30 CDP 7 1.04 11 (14) 0.79 1.30 CDP 8 0.47 17 (19) 0.43 1.30 CDP 9 1.96 7 (17) 1.23 1.30 CDP 10 0.42 15 (17) 0.37 1.30 CDP 19 7.12 6 (12) 2.49 1.30 CDP 20 1.49 9 (12) 2.26 1.30 CDP 23 2.46 9 (12) 3.34 1.30 CDP 27 1.26 15 (22) 0.59 1.30 CDP 33 1.75 8 (12) 1.41 1.30 CDP 34 1.39 14 (21) 0.95 1.30 CDP 53 0.35 18 (19) 0.56 1.30 CDP 68 20.40 1 (21) 17.68 1.30 CDP 72 2.09 10 (16) 2.02 1.30 CDP 78 0.54 18 (18) 1.05 1.30 CDP 81 1.19 12 (16) 0.58 1.30 CDP 84 3.83 8 (18) 0.84 1.30 CDP 86 2.12 13 (21) 1.48 1.30 CDP 88 10.29 4 (18) 1.87 1.30 CDP 90 0.44 20 (25) 0.93 1.30 CDP 91 1.30 13 (15) 1.31 1.30 CDP 92 0.92 6 (11) 1.63 1.30 CDP 93 1.30 13 (18) 1.43 1.30 CDP 94 1.97 12 (20) 1.58 1.30 CDP 95 1.92 10 (26) 1.80 1.30 CDP 96 2.36 11 (21) 1.55 1.30 CDP 114 1.14 13 (23) 0.71 1.30 CDP 115 1.32 11 (15) 0.77 1.30 CDP 117 0.86 13 (21) 0.76 1.30 "9 The value in parentheses is the number of candidates in the given district. 12° Includes candidates that were members of the party and appeared on the ballot as affiliated. Because of this, the number of sponsored candidates in Table 13 differs slightly from this table. 121 Includes ”against all.” 122 The value in parentheses is the number of candidates in the given district. 138 Table 21 (cont’d) CDP 118 7.16 5 (15) 1.78 1.30 CDP 119 1.02 11 (14) 1.47 1.30 CDP 121 0.61 10 (10) 1.75 1.30 CDP 122 3.78 9 (20) 1.80 1.30 CDP 123 1.54 11 (16) 2.03 1.30 CDP 124123 9.43 3 (12) 1.46 1.30 CDP 126 1.66 8 (18) 3.08 1.30 CDP 138 2.29 7 (17) 1.17 1.30 CDP 139 4.23 5 (19) 1.77 1.30 CDP 144 1.61 9 (27) 1.07 1.30 CDP 145 0.99 17 (22) 1.03 1.30 CDP 150 0.54 18 (26) 1.35 1.30 CDP 153 2.20 10 (22) 2.28 1.30 CDP 154 0.35 22 (23) 1.98 1.30 CDP 155 3.29 6 (14) 3.52 1.30 CDP 156 0.83 16 (22) 3.07 1.30 CDP 157 0.54 21 (21) 0.89 1.30 CDP 163 2.66 9 (17) 1.75 1.30 CDP 164 1.09 17 (24) 2.75 1.30 CDP 165 1.23 10 (17) 2.81 1.30 CDP 166 2.25 9 (17) 1.48 1.30 CDP 174 3.53 7 (21) 1.03 1.30 CDP 182 2.15 9 (19) 2.44 1.30 CDP 183 24.33 1 (22) 8.16 1.30 CDP 188 0.83 13 (20) 1.71 1.30 CDP 189 1.71 12 (16) 1.64 1.30 CDP 190 0.90 14 (16) 1.92 1.30 CDP 191 2.92 11 (18) 3.68 1.30 CDP 200 1.73 11 (18) 0.77 1.30 CDP 201 1.02 14 (19) 1.02 1.30 CDP 205 0.93 17 (19) 1.81 1.30 CDP 206 0.99 14 (21) 0.86 1.30 CDP 215 1.34 10 (24) 1.92 1.30 CDP 224 0.27 18 (19) 0.55 1.30 CDP 225 1.65 11 (19) 0.42 1.30 ‘23 Two candidates appeared on the ballot as CDP candidates in the district. I report the results for the best performing candidate. 139 0n probe there doe HC pr0p0rti0. aggregate tended to level. Th placemer. detail in ti Conclusit Thel electOra) c itSUQgesti SMD- Poi pamCipath fewer reso One dictate We are “RF-1y t: Margina) p. Were Door l Winners in 1 on probable winners. While some parties clustered candidates geographically, there does not seem to be a general pattern of placement based on geography. However, SMD candidates for marginal parties received a higher proportion of the vote in their respective districts than the party received in the aggregate. In districts where these small parties placed candidates, the party tended to receive a higher proportion of votes in PR than it did at the aggregate level. This suggests that there may be an additional connection between placement in SMD and performance in PR, 8 relationship that will be analyzed in detail in the next chapter. Conclusions The Investment Effect predicts that parties that have committed to electoral competition are likely to participate fully in the mixed system. Further, it suggests that party resources partially dictate the degree of participation in SMD. Political parties that are more able to overcome the marginal costs of participation in SMD are likely to sponsor more candidates than those that have fewer resources. One possible alternative explanation to the argument that resources dictate placement strategies in SMD is that parties place SMD candidates that are likely to win. The evidence does not support this contention, however. Marginal parties in all three countries generally placed candidates in SMD that were poor performers. It is unlikely that they were considered to be probable winners in the districts. 140 have a candic factors the vol raises placen Contan Candid Another alternate explanation is that parties place candidates where they have a regional base of support. While some parties concentrated their candidates in a particular region, this was not true for most parties. Other factors may motivate parties in their placement decisions. An additional finding, that parties tend to receive a higher proportion of the vote locally than nationally in districts where they place SMD candidates, raises the possibility that there is an additional effect influencing SMD placement. In the next chapter, I will discuss the Echo Effect — a form of contamination that encourages parties to participate in SMD, even if their candidates have little prospect of winning seats in the districts. 141 Chapter 5 THE ECHO EFFECT The prevalence of multiparty competition in mixed systems is not surprising, given the relatively forgiving nature of the mechanical effect, established in Chapter 3, and the Investment Effect, analyzed in Chapter 4. The Echo Effect provides further incentives for multipartism in mixed systems. A party’s sponsorship of a candidate in SMD races can improve vote outcomes for the party in PR.124 Through advertising and active campaigning, local SMD candidates would raise awareness of the party, increasing the likelihood that the party would receive votes in PR. Even if the candidates are not active campaigners, a party’s affiliation with a SMD candidate on the ballot may encourage support for the party in PR by voters who otherwise would not have voted for the party.125 Aggregated to the national level, this effect could increase the number of seats that a party gains in parliament. The name “Echo Effect” is derived from these direct and indirect effects. The improvement of local PR outcomes based on SMD candidate placement is 124 In other words, affiliation with a candidate can have benefits whether or not the candidate is popular or powerful. If the candidate is also well-known and well-connected to local political and economic resources, the benefits accruing to the party could be even greater. ‘25 It Is possible that participation of some candidates may have a negative effect on PR performance as well - a non-charismatic individual could hurt the party in PR. Also, some parties might benefit from the lack of information about their actual platform - voters may be more likely to support the image of the party rather than the substance. If the SMD candidate increases knowledge about the party’s positions, it could damage the party’s performance. Despite these possible scenarios, parties presumably field candidates that they expect will help their overall performance. Moreover, the effect of increasing awareness of the party should generally be positive. 142 the direct effect. The indirect aspect (or echo) is the strategic response of parties to the potential electoral benefits. The Echo Effect Hypothesis indicates that the placement of candidates in SMD will affect vote outcomes in PR in corresponding districts. If the effect is borne out by the evidence, the positive effect of SMD placement on PR performance should further encourage parties to maximize the placement of candidates in SMD. As I will show, the data support the existence of the Echo Effect in all elections under analysis. Echo Effect Hypothesis, Models 1a and 1b Results for Model 1a Lithuania’s 1996 parliamentary elections provide support for the Echo Effect. The variable SMDPL measures placement across the districts (71 in Lithuania). A statistically significant coefficient means that the placement of a candidate in an SMD race directly affects vote outcomes in PR. In Model 1a, controls are added for incumbency and for the party’s local popularity. Of the eleven parties analyzed, the parameter value of SMDPL is statistically significant and positive in sign in all but one instance (see Table 22). The magnitude of the SMDPL’s effect also varies, as we would expect. Because SMDPL’s coefficient represents the local bonus received by a party in PR from placing a candidate in a district race, parties that received more support in the elections should generally obtain higher coefficient values than parties that did not perform as well. 143 Table 22: OLS Results for Model 1a (Lithuania 1996) CDU Econ LCU LLU Constant 3579*” .944 3889*” .345 (.545) (.645) (1.004) (.631) ,BISMDPL .243 1 .371 ** 2.999" 1 979*“ (607) (580) (928) (567) lencumbent 3.138“ 6.316” (1.123) (2.351) flJUrban -.008 -.008 .036” .009 (.007) (.009) (.013) (.009) Adjusted R2 .109 .049 .305 .175 N 71 71 71 71 Table 22 (cont’d) LNU LL Peasants Poles Alliance Constant 3.780*** .238 *** 3600*" 5.009” (.401) (.033) (.454) (2.365) ,BISMDPL 2507*”r .201 *** 1 .170“ 10.845*** (.411) (.032) (.342) (2.217) lencumbent __ _ 7.103” 7.856 (1.378) (8.711) ,63Urban -.005 -.001 -.028*** -.007** (.005) (.000) (.005) (.032) Adjusted R2 .337 .345 .560 .274 N 71 71 71 71 144 Table 22 (cont’d) Pol. Socialists Women Prisoners Constant .851 .589*** 3.248*** (1.037) (.082) (.506) ,BISMDPL 1.391 ** .372*** 1.157“ (.454) (.078) (.377) lencumbent 8.553” .055 __ (1.341) (.297) ,B3Urban .012 .011 .001 (024) (001) (006) Adjusted R2 .314 .239 .100 N 71 71 71 Dependent Variable: Proportion of the vote in PR at the SMD level. Standard Errors are in parentheses. * ps.10 ** p305 *** ps.01 145 For example, by placing candidates in SMD, the LCU accrued a mean bonus of 3.0%. In the entire system, the LCU received 7.7% of the vote, so the magnitude of its local bonus in PR is proportionate to its overall performance.126 This tendency carries over to very small parties in the analysis. The Party of Life’s Logic received 0.3% of the total vote.127 At 0.2%, its local bonus for placing a candidate was quite high. A small coefficient does not indicate that the bonus itself was small; it is dependent on the relative size of the bonus in comparison to the party’s overall performance. Small parties generally had small parameter values for SMDPL; larger parties had larger ones. The statistical significance of the coefficients for the control variables varies. Five parties had no incumbents participating in the election. Of the remaining six parties, INCUMBENT is statistically significant in four cases. The coefficient value for INCUMBENT is higher than the coefficient for SMDPL in each case, suggesting that incumbency provides a greater benefit for party performance in PR than simply placing a candidate in the district. The proxy for popularity, URBAN, is statistically significant in three of the eleven cases and demonstrates the expected effect. The sign of the coefficient is negative for the Lithuanian Peasants’ Party, indicating that the party performs better in PR in rural areas. The coefficient of SMDPL is statistically significant in these three cases, indicating that the inclusion of a proxy for popularity does not undermine the Echo Effect in Lithuania. ‘26 The LCU received 8.2% of the vote in PR and 6.8% of the vote in SMD. ‘27 The Party of Life’s Logic received 0.24% of the vote in PR and 0.33% of the vote in SMD. 146 All cases were tested for collinearity and the influence of outliers. Generally, the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF) was close to one, indicating that collinearity should not undermine the efficiency of the parameters.128 Outliers had a limited effect on the results. The removal of extreme outliers recovered the significance of the constant in the case of the Lithuanian Party of the Economy, but there were no substantial changes in other cases.129 Results for Model 1b While the Lithuanian model controlled for urban/rural residence only, the Russian and Ukrainian models also control for level of education. Just as the proportion of urban dwellers in a region should provide a proxy for popularity, so too should the composition of a region’s population by education. By adding this variable, we raise our confidence that we have adequately controlled for the alternative hypothesis. Table 23 shows OLS results for ten Russian political parties in the 1995 Duma elections. The signs of the coefficients for SMDPL are positive, except in the case of NDR. The parameter of SMDPL is significant at the .05 level in seven of the models and at the .10 level in an additional model. The KPRF received the largest average bonus for candidate placement, at 4.7%. ‘28 The VIF measures how a coefficient’s variance is inflated by collinearity. As collinearity increases in the model, the VIF uses. The VIF measures how a coefficient’s variance is inflated by collinearity. See Gujarati (1995, 328-329) for more information. 1 Outliers beyond three standard deviations from the mean were identified and removed from the dataset. The data were then re-analyzed with each individual outlier removed and with all outliers removed as a block. 147 Table 23: OLS Results for Model 1b (Russia 1995) APR DVR Forward, KPRF KRO Russia Constant 13.652*** -3.240*** -.254 33.862*** 1.656“ (1.441) (.744) (.274) (2.874) (.717) ,3, .981 .924" .662*** 4.726*** 1.792*** SMDPL (.616) (.327) (.125) (1.194) (.295) ,3, 2.952" 2.987*** .742" 5.559" 1.595 incumbent (1.077) (.675) (.352) (2.343) (1.266) p, -.140*** .003" .025*** -.170*** .017 Urban (.024) (.013) (.005) (.049) (.013) p, -.002 .429*** .023 -.241 .064* Education (.076) (.040) (.015) (.156) (.009) Adjusted R2 .273 .608 .362 .210 .209 N 225 225 225 225 225 148 Table 23 (cont’d): KTR LDPR NDR Rybkin Yabloko Constant 8.337*** 11.125*** 8.122*** 1.552*** 4359*“ (.609) (1.753) (2.140) (.384) (1.011) p, 1.180*** 1505* -.074 .587” 2.471*** SMDPL (.274) (.854) (.858) (.192) (.460) '32 4595* .544 1.15*** 2112* Incumbent (2.423) (3.122) (.325) (1.286) p, -.032** .044 -.054 -.008 .007*** Urban (.011) (.028) (.036) (.007) (.018) p, -.154*** -.649*** .571*** .003 .431*** Education (.033) (.088) (.115) (.021) (.055) Adjusted R2 .282 .268 .116 .155 .576 N 225 225 225 225 225 ps.10 p305 p301 149 Dependent Variable: Proportion of the vote in PR at the SMD level. Standard errors are in parentheses. Among the control variables, INCUMBENT is statistically significant at the .05 level in five of nine cases and at the .10 level in two cases.‘3° Just as in Lithuania, the parameter value of INCUMBENT exceeds the value of SMDPL in each case where INCUMBENT is statistically significant. This indicates that incumbency status exerts a greater impact on local PR performance than candidate placement. The signs and statistical significance of URBAN and EDUCATION, proxies for regional popularity, varied. The coefficient for URBAN was significant and positive in sign for DVR, Forward, Russia, and Yabloko. It was significant and negative for the APR, KPRF and KTR. Thus, pro-reform and pro-Western parties tended to receive support in cities while communist and agrarian parties received support in rural regions. The parameter value of EDUCATION was significant and positive for DVR, KRO, NDR and Yabloko. These parties received a higher proportion of the PR vote in regions with a higher proportion of educated residents. It was significant and negative for KTR and the LDPR, demonstrating that these parties received less support where a region’s population was more highly educated. Just as the results from the 1996 Seimas elections in Lithuania provided support for the existence of the Echo Effect, so too do the results from Russia’s 131 1995 parliamentary elections. When controls are added for incumbency and 13° The variable could not be included in the KTR equation because the party had no incumbents in 1995. 131 The results of diagnostic tests for collinearity and outliers showed that they did not exert a substantial impact on the results. 150 Table 24: OLS Results for Russia (1999) AN-SF DN KPRF KRO LDPR Constant .224** .044*** 39.356*** -.538**'* 5.381*** (088) (.017) (1.206) (.172) (.725) ,3, .122*** .040*** 2152* .436*** .041 SMDPL (.038) (.007) (1.206) (.085) (.297) [32 .462** .164*** 2.874** 2.403*** 1.716* incumbent (.192) (.025) (1.284) (.511) (.897) ,3, .004*** .000 -.181*** .006** .048*** Urban (.002) (.000) (.043) (.003) (.013) )3, -.001 .000 -.41 1*** .056*** -.255*** Education (.005) (.001) (.132) (.009) (.039) Adjusted R2 .139 .322 .327 .424 .164 N 224132 224 224 224 224 ‘32 The number of cases is 224 because no elections were held in Chechnya. 151 Table 24 (cont’d): NDR OVR RSP SPS Yabloko Constant 1 .537*** 7.932** .279*** -3.863*** -3.046*** (.496) (3.880) (.080) (1.356) (.901) ,3, .083 2.007 .117*** .928 1.494*** SMDPL (.216) (1.655) (.037) (.610) (.369) p, .474 5.099 .679*** 2.840 .768 incumbent (.336) (4.000) (.1 10) (1.868) (.616) p, -.006 -.213*** -.002 .181*** .098*** Urban (.009) (.068) (.001) (.024) (.015) p, .026 1.753*** .007* -.096 094* Education (.005) (.213) (.004) (.073) (.48) Adjusted R2 .000 .291 .221 .306 .387 N 224 224 224 224 224 Dependent Variable: Proportion of the vote in PR at the SMD level. Standard errors are in parentheses. p s .10 p s .05 *** p301 152 popularity, the effect of SMD candidate placement remains in most of the cases. This provides additional evidence for the Echo Effect. Russia’s 1999 results also support the existence of the Echo Effect, although they are less consistent than the 1995 analysis. The results in Table 24 show that the coefficient for SMDPL is statistically significant at .05 for five models and at .10 in an additional model. The strength of the SMD effect is highest for the KPRF, which received a 2.2% bonus, on average, by placing candidates in SMD. The coefficient for INCUMBENT was also significant at the .05 level in five cases and at the .10 level in an additional case. Once again, the effect of incumbency on PR vote outcomes is stronger in all of the cases in which the parameter is statistically significant. The coefficients for urban residence and education vary from party to party. The parameter value of URBAN is statistically significant and positive in sign for the Bloc of Andrey Nikolayev and Svyatoslav Fyodorov (AN-SF), KRO, LDPR, SP8 and Yabloko. The relationship between urban residence and PR performance for Yabloko remained the same in both 1995 and 1999; the party tends to receive a higher proportion of PR votes as the proportion of the population in the region is more urban. The coefficient is negative for the KPRF and Fatherland - All Russia (OVR). This is not surprising given that the APR dissolved during the 1999 election campaign and prominent members joined forces with both the KPRF and OVR. Moreover, the sign of URBAN was negative for the KPRF in 1995 and remained negative in 1999. 153 The coefficient for EDUCATION was positive and significant at the .05 level for KRO and OVR, and at the .10 level for the Russian Socialist Party (RSP) and Yabloko. These results are consistent with those from 1995. The parameter is significant and negative for the KPRF and LDPR. This is also consistent with 1995. In sum, results from Russia support the Echo Effect Hypothesis. In both 1995 and 1999, the coefficient for SMDPL is significant in most cases. The results are less consistent during the 1999 elections, a phenomenon that will be addressed below. The OLS analysis with Ukrainian data also supports the Echo Effect Hypothesis, even in the presence of controls for incumbency and popularity (see Table 25, columns labeled 1b). The variable SMDPL is statistically significant at the .05 level in seven of thirteen cases and at the .10 level in an additional case. Incumbency is statistically significant in ten of twelve cases and at the .10 level in a single case.133 As in other countries, the bonus for candidate placement varies from party to party. The larger parties, such as KPU, receive larger bonuses than more marginal parties, such as UNA. The KPU bonus for candidate placement is 6.6% compared to the UNA’s .51%. Thus, the KPU could expect to receive a 6.6% bonus, on average, in PR in districts where it placed an SMD candidate; UNA could expect .51%. The KPU received 20.3% of the total vote; UNA received ‘33 One of the parties had no incumbents in the 1998 elections. 154 mmm mmm mmm mum mmm mmm mmm cum 2 8mm. «2. ova. wt. #0. 80.. Pm. mos. am passes. A341 663 E: 868 Lee: iooom. icon. 33. £83 as E: 803 3:3 883 Loom S? can- moor men. as ammo as; 88$ 833 88.5 48.- :33- out- So. as $63 68.3 88c an“: ANNE 853 $83 $3 cosecscm :18. icon. meo. tho. e8. .58. ac. moo. 4n 3:: :63 8:: £63 C83 :83 A83 8:: secs £50.- £50.- moor immor 2.85.- £20.- 98.- £68.- an :33 C :3 am: am: 8%. : Ev. : accesses inc; tween 80. 80. £83 icons e. 863 :03 A83 am: 8e: 8?: can: as: dog toes. the. tone. .mvm. m1. mm: mob. mmo. an $63 ammo A83 803 as; 53 83”.: :03 £656 $23 New. famed £83 £83 £83 inc: E8628 m e m e m 8 m 8 Lone: EoQ ocoeco moo 69m 2%. End some cases. u can be mace: 5.. ozone”. «Jo "mu e38. 155 mNN mNN mNN mNN mNN mNN mNN mNN 2 SN. N8. t e. 8 F. can. SN. 48. one. am ceases. 68.5 at; 83.5 8N9 5 one: £ 55,1 Em. £33: £899- as 68.5 a 5.5 88.5 a a. 5 Loam £o 5N Eb. cam. :05...” as ASN.5 $8.5 $8.5 ENNNV 6685 5:. :o. 86.- £58: 5. 60 e .5 Go F .5 £85 53 EN e .5 so: 543 ASN.5 68856.5 £36. Nmor N8. m 5. £ :3. £6 5. £8N. e- £85 F- as 88.5 2&3 a :5 a 6.5 :85 $8.5 $8.5 :85 :25 88.5 aNNNv 85.5 33.5 834.5 82.5 385 88.5 accesses SN .33 £2 e .6 £5 e .6 £83 £F {a tNNoe :33 as 88.5 Not 88.5 83.5 68.5 68.5 ace. 5 6.8. 5 udosm Eb. £83 :62. :85 N 3. one. :82” £938 5. :2. 5 GNN. 5 :35 ft 68. 5 as. 5 88.5 :8va £68.? owNe £82 £53 NNme £5NN £858 86.- 5:65:60 N 2 N 2 N 2 N 2 Lace: com 652 u 52 3% End 6.28. 3 can... 156 mNN mNN mNN mNN mNN mNN 2 SN. .35 one. 8N. 8m. 8N. am some}. 68. 5 863 Co: as: £85m- £68N 93. st :8. 5 68.5 AcNi seem .mkN- 8N.- £83 as 63.5 A83 as: 85.5 £83. tmET me..- he ASN.5 Cm: $8.5 $8.5 $8.5 $3.5 coco-56m 08.. 8? £EN. £30 £5:- £RN.- Q $8.5 N35 8N3 $5.5 ES :55 :35 £30- £55- 08. £89 £86. £26. an 38.5 8R5 ASN.5 $8.5 68.5 88.5 Emcee-cs Soc :33 £83 £83 £82” £83” an 885 El. 5 8:; EN: 5N5 63.5 .EQEm mN: New. £5: £vaN EN. EN. as some aNva 89. 5 act ENE :35 £8NNN £423 me:- £me.m 65.- £955 5988 N e N S N S Loco: 69m mem cam BEBE End 6.2.85 mN each 157 S.wau£ ”mode": Norman .- .momo£c8ma 5 8m 22cm Eons—Em ._m>o_ 056 35 “m an. E 90> on. ,6 cos-.89.". 8385) E32800 m-NN mNN mNN mNN 2 Be. be. 68. 08. am 8532 :35 83 Lacs £05. .8? S 83.5 it 58m 80.- m8. .6. A8: :55 8E5 .8? 88.7 as 85.5 88.5 83 83.5 cosmoscm £08. £N8. £83. £63. 8. 88.5 N03 ENS ES :85 30.- £e E.- £mNor £86.- 8 ASN.5 2 N5 ANNvé 68.5 568585 .58. £85 £858 £858 8 88.5 88.5 at; 83 .Eosa £834. £88. oR. i8. e s. $3.5 28.5 83. 5 68.5 3:. £58. £83 £83 59860 N 2 N 5 L86: <2: :58 E8 6.2.8. 8 c.52- 158 .41 % of the total.134 Thus, the average bonus received by these parties is proportionate to their overall performance in the election. Moreover, both large and small parties show measurable effects. The coefficient for URBAN was statistically significant in all but one case. The coefficient values represent the effect of a one percent change in the urban population on PR performance. For the KPU, an increase in 1% in the urban population results in a .53% improvement in PR results at the district level. URBAN was significant and positive for the KPU and RAZOM. It was significant and negative for APU, Bloc of Democratic Parties (Bloc Dem), Christian Democratic Party (CDP), Greens, National Front (Nat F), People’s Democratic Party (NDP), Reform and Order (R&O), Socialist and Peasant Bloc (S&P Bloc), Social Democratic Party (United) (SDPU) and UNA. The parameter estimate of EDUCATION is statistically significant a the .05 level in eight cases. It is significant at the .10 level in an additional case. Again using the KPU as an example, a one percent increase in the proportion of population with a higher education results in a 1.5% reduction in the PR vote. EDUCATION is significant at .05 and positive for CDP, Greens, Nat F, R&O, SDPU and UNA. It is significant and negative for KPU and RAZOM. In addition to assessing the effects of the explanatory variables, I conducted diagnostic tests for collinearity and the influence of outliers. The control variables presented some problems of collinearity, but this does not introduce bias into the model. As expected, URBAN and EDUCATION are highly ‘34 The KPU received 24.65% of the PR vote; KPU candidates gained 13.38% of the SMD vote. UNA garnered .40% of PR and UNA candidates received .38% of the SMD vote. 159 correlated; better educated individuals tend to be urban dwellers. While the VIF reached as high as 4 for URBAN and EDUCATION for some parties, SMDPL does not become significant for all parties even when URBAN and EDUCATION are removed. The increase in inefficiency caused by the control variables does not explain the failure of the Echo Effect to be manifested for each party. Outliers also had a measurable effect on the results. Removing outliers and repeating the analysis altered the outcomes in some cases. The p value for SMDPL was raised to .32 after removing the outlying case in the CDP model. While individually removing the outliers and testing the model did not affect the results greatly for the Greens, removing the entire block of outliers raised the p value of SMDPL to .11. Removing outliers did not uniformly undermine the Echo Effect, however. With the PSP model, the p value of URBAN became .02 after removing all outliers, rendering that coefficient statistically significant. Removing all outliers in the APU case also improved results. The variable SMDPL, which was not significant with outliers included, became statistically significant when outliers were removed (the p value became .03). However, the significance of INCUMBENT was lost in the APU model when outliers were removed. The same effect was found in the RAZOM model. Removing the block of outliers recovered an effect of SMDPL, changing its p-value to .01. Likewise, the p-value of SMDPL became .01 with all outliers removed for the Block of Democratic Parties. Outliers have a measurable effect on the results in the Ukrainian case. While it is instructive to remove outliers and reanalyze the data in order to assess 160 their effect, it is also important to note that outliers are real cases. That is, we cannot simply remove them because they do not fit within our predictions. Outliers also failed to affect the results in one direction; they did not uniformly undermine or support contamination effects. In some models the effect was lost, in others it was recovered. Overall, however, when outliers are removed, evidence for the Echo Effect improves. Evidence from additional mixed systems suggests that the results are robust. Although the assessments of the Echo Effect in Germany, New Zealand and Japan do not include the same variables as the analysis in this chapter, they support the hypothesis in compensatory systems as well as established democratic states with institutionalized party systems (see Appendix C for details). Russia’s 1999 and Ukraine’s 1998 elections are the least consistent in demonstrating the existence of the Echo Effect. It is possible that the benefits accruing to large parties diminish over time. As voters become more aware of the party’s existence, the simple act of placing a candidate on the ballot may have a less substantial effect on the PR vote. Because Russia has conducted the most elections under the mixed system, the deterioration of the effect may have begun to manifest itself in the 1999 elections. Another possibility is that the influence of regional authorities could undermine the Echo Effect. There have been claims of vote fraud in some regions that affected the major parties (KPRF, LDPR, Medved, OVR, and SP8 in 161 particular).135 If regional governors indeed altered the results for these parties in PR, the apparent effect of SMDPL on PR vote outcomes could be affected. Alternatively, regional governors could use their administrative resources to favor candidates that are affiliated with their parties. This could also affect the relationship between SMDPL and local PR outcomes. In fact, if the governor’s party affiliation is added to the equation, it significantly affects the PR performance of the major parties. The affiliations of regional governors were based on stated affiliations and membership in leadership councils (McFauI, Petrov, Ryabov and Reisch 1999). Only four political parties had close ties with regional authorities, limiting the analysis. The KPRF has a strong regional base, stemming from its inheritance of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union’s organizational capacity. While the KPRF enjoys support in many regions of the country, it is particularly strong in the so-called “Red Belt,” 8 set of regions along Russia’s southern tier. The other three parties, NDR, OVR and Medved, have been considered the “parties of power” with close ties to the central leadership. NDR, headed by former Prime Minister Viktor Chernomyrdin, was the “party of power” in the 1995 elections. OVR, led by former Prime Minister Yevgeniy Primakov and Moscow Mayor Yuriy Luzhkov, was the early favorite in the 1999 elections until it fell out of President Yeltsin’s favor. Medved was the political bloc supported by Vladimir Putin, Boris Yeltsin’s chosen successor for the presidential office. All three ‘35 Claims of fraud have circulated through Johnson's Russia List (a listserv). In addition, the author has spoken with regional scholars who argue that there was some systematic fraud. 162 Table 26: OLS Results for Model 1b with Controls for Gubernatorial Affiliation (Russia 1999) KPRF MED NDR OVR Constant 37.338*** 34.032W .945“ 1 5067*” (2.494) (2.872) (.471) (3.599) )3, 2.456“ 1.256 .000 1.438 SMDPL (1.150) (1.673) (.201) (1.482) p, 2161* -2.721 .426 2.891 incumbent (1.232) (6.052) (.312) (3.598) p, -.176*** -.007 -.000 -.320*** Urban (.041) (.050) (.008) (.062) )3, -.343*** -.933*** .005 1.425*** Education (.127) (.151) (.024) (.196) p, 6392*” 4.163” 1.763*** 12.193*** Governor (1.328) (1.982) (.293) (1.635) Adjusted R2 .389 .256 .139 .433 N 224 224 224 224 Dependent Variable: Proportion of the vote in PR at the SMD level. Standard errors are in parentheses. * ps.10 ** p505 *** p301 163 parties were considered, at one point, to be the party preferred by the central leadership. Because of this, many regional governors chose to ally with these groups to gain benefits from affiliation with the center. The unique position of these parties allows us to code them based on gubernatorial support. The results of the analysis are found on Table 26. While the statistical significance of the parameter values for SMDPL do not change from the results in Table 21, the parameter for the affiliation of governors is statistically significant and positive in sign in all four cases. In other words, parties performed better in regions where the governor was officially connected to that party. This suggests that governors may have substantial influence over the electorate and electoral process and that their authority affects vote outcomes. This could undermine the connection between candidate placement in SMD and performance in PR. Thus, the failure of SMDPL to display statistical significance for some parties in the most recent Russian election may be due, in part, to the latter explanation. This is not the only possible rival explanation for the results, however. Echo Effect Hypothesis, Model 2 — The Effect of Regionalism Extending the analysis to Ukraine raises an important question about the robustness of the Echo Effect. Ukraine is a country with long-standing regional divisions that could undermine our confidence in the existence of contamination effects. The mechanism by which regionalism could be confounded with contamination was outlined in detail in the Chapter 3. The argument is similar to the alternative hypothesis about the effect of popularity: parties place candidates 164 in areas where they have regional bases of support. If the effects we attribute to the Echo Effect actually reflect careful candidate placement based on geography, they would be incorrectly interpreted as an institutional effect. If parties with regional bases of support place candidates in regions outside their strongholds, they may not receive the corresponding “bonus” in PR vote outcomes. Table 27 shows that candidate placement and performance for some parties varies substantially by region.136 For instance, the performance of the National Front (Nat F) appears to depend heavily on the region. In western oblasts, it received, on average, 7% of the local PR vote. It accrued less than 1% in all other regions. This disparity in performance is not limited to Nat F; other parties also depend on support from particular regions. Given that regionalism is entrenched in Ukraine’s political system, are contamination effects robust when we control for regions? The effect of SMDPL loses its statistical significance in two cases (PSP and SDPU) when we control for regions (see Table 25, columns labeled Model 2). The coefficient value for SMD also drops in some cases (such as KPU and R80), suggesting that regionalism may have an attenuating effect on the Echo Effect. The regional variables vary in terms of their significance. CRIMEA is significant at the .05 level in four cases; EAST is significant in three; WEST is significant in nine. The sign of the coefficients also varies. For the variable WEST, the coefficient is positive for the APU, CDP, Nat F, R80 and UNA. ‘36 Candidate affiliations are based on party membership rather than party sponsorship. 165 Table 27: Mean PR Vote and Number of Candidates by Region (Ukraine 1998)137 Central Crimea East West (86 SMD) (12 SMD) (64 SMD) (63 SMD) APU 2.85 2.82 2.27 5.69 49 2 22 36 BIocDem 1.28 1.07 0.96 1.43 36 1 22 28 CDP 1.22 0.58 0.59 2.12 21 12 6 29 Greens 6.59 5.80 5.05 4.65 40 4 28 26 KPU 25.10 40.39 35.72 12.19 63 12 58 41 Nat F 0.94 0.20 0.33 7.04 56 3 34 48 NDP 4.71 5.14 4.42 5.84 52 5 33 35 PSP 3.76 1.41 7.53 1.67 25 0 33 7 RAZOM 1.33 0.63 4.01 1.19 30 10 37 27 R80 2.43 0.98 2.73 4.89 17 2 30 23 S&P 11.07 1.60 4.67 8.45 39 8 38 38 SDPU 3.90 1.94 2.67 6.09 40 0 32 27 UNA 0.35 0.09 0.18 0.70 18 0 10 22 ‘37 The mean proportion of PR votes for the region is on top. The number of candidates in SMD races is below. Number of candidates refers to candidates that appeared on the SMD ballot as affiliated with the party. 166 The sign is negative for the Greens, KPU, PSP and the S&P Bloc. These results are not surprising. The CDP, Nat F and UNA are parties that have promoted Ukrainian nationalist positions. Thus, we would expect them to compete successfully in the West. The KPU and PSP reflect ideologies associated with the former communist system and are expected to perform poorly in the area with the strongest manifestations of Ukrainian national pride. The analysis was accompanied by diagnostic tests for collinearity and the influence of outliers in all of the models. The problems of collinearity were similar to those found in Model 1b. The variables URBAN and EDUCATION and URBAN and CRIMEA were usually highly correlated. In the former case, we would expect more educated individuals to live in cities. In the latter case, most districts in the Crimean region are in urban areas. Nevertheless, the increase in inefficiency due to collinearity did not exert a substantial impact on the results. Removing outliers and repeating the analysis altered the results in some cases. In the case of the Greens, removing the outliers raised the p-value of SMDPL beyond the .05 level. This only occurred when all outliers were removed as a block, however. Removing all outliers “recovered” the statistical significance of SMDPL for APU, Bloc Dem and RAZOM, however. In summary, including regional variables in Ukraine mitigates the effect of contamination in some cases, but the Echo Effect is generally robust. While sociological characteristics, specifically regionalism, seem to interact with the institutional factors and attenuate the Echo Effect, the effects attributable to institutions do not disappear. 167 Echo Effect Hypothesis, Model 3 — The Effect of Independent Candidates Just as gubernatorial party affiliation affected PR vote outcomes in Russia and regionalism exerted an impact on PR results in Ukraine, another prominent factor in the elections could affect the relationship between SMD placement and PR performance in these countries. The large number of independent candidates who participated in elections could produce an artificial Echo Effect. If voters, contributors and other political actors know the ideological preferences of officially independent candidates, our measure of interaction may be inadequate. Because we do not account for interactive effects among candidates who are not officially affiliated with a political movement, but whose “true” affiliation is known, we eliminate a large proportion of active candidates from the analysis. If these covert partisans’ real affiliations are well-known among the voters, contributors and other candidates, the data may be censored. Data collected by the Ukrainian Central Electoral Commission facilitates a analysis of the effect of covert partisans on PR outcomes. While the CEC collected data about the membership status and sponsorship of candidates, only party membership appears on the ballot. For example, a candidate might be a member of the NDP but not be sponsored by the party on the ballot. That candidate would appear on the ballot, however, as a member of the NDP. Because parties cannot fully control the decisions of their members, there were numerous instances in which the party ran an official candidate and another party member also contested the seat. On the ballot, it appeared as if the party had two candidates in the district. 168 In addition, a candidate without an official party affiliation (labeled “‘bezpartiiniy”) could be nominated by a party on a local ballot. In this case, the candidate would appear to be independent, but actually would be affiliated with a political party. Because party membership alone was published on the ballot, many covert partisans participated in the elections.138 Covert partisans are defined as candidates with no party membership who are nominated by a party in the SMD component of the system. I included the variable COVPART to control for the role of nominal independents who were sponsored by a party. These candidates’ ideological leanings could be known to the voters. Table 28 shows the number of districts with covert partisans for each party under analysis. OLS results show that covert partisanship has a limited but important impact on the Echo Effect (see Table 29). The variable COVPART is statistically significant for only two political parties. In both cases, the inclusion of covert partisanship renders the variable SMDPL statistically significant as well. For Bloc Dem, the bonus received by having a candidate in SMD is 24%. Covert partisans improve performance by 70%. A similar relationship is found with the UNA. The coefficient for SMDPL is .48; the COVPART coefficient is .58. In other words, covert partisans exert a stronger influence on PR performance than party members in these instances. In the remaining cases, covert partisanship has no measurable effect on the results. ‘38 To register in an SMD race, a candidate must either have been nominated by a party and present proof of nomination or collect 900 signatures and obtain self-nominated status (“On the Election of People's Deputies of Ukraine,” Article 25, as amended (NAU 1999)). 169 Removing extreme outliers from the analysis affects some parties. The coefficient for SMDPL becomes significant for APU and NDP, but it is raised above the .10 level for Greens. The statistical significance of coefficients for some other parties change, but do not undermine my substantive conclusions. Table 28: Number of Covert Partisans for Ukraine (1998) Party Number of Covert Partisans APU 16 Bloc Dem 16 CDP 7 Greens 29 KPU 7 Nat F 36 NDP 1 1 PSP 15 RAZOM 22 R80 24 S&P Bloc 19 SDPU 41 UNA 4 To summarize, by developing a measure of covert partisanship for independents, we see that it has a slight influence on our assessment of the Echo Effect. The results of the analysis do not undermine the existence of effect, but enhance our confidence in it. When we control for covert partisanship, we recover an effect that is lost in the existing coding scheme in two cases. This suggests that some of our failures to find evidence of the Echo Effect may be due to the influence of covert partisans and not a weakness of contamination effects. The influence of covert partisanship potentially extends to Russia as well. The instability in Russian results could also be due to the existence of covert 170 Table 29: OLS Results for Model 3 (Ukraine 1998) APU Bloc Dem CDP Greens KPU Constant 3.425” 1 .863*** .830 6990*“ 20.614*** (1.364) (.339) (.528) (.911) (3.985) ,3, .735 .243** .501 ** .640“ 3.961 ** SMDPL (.448) (.120) (.209) (.309) (1.580) '32 5724*“ .048 3.153*** 3.996“ Incumbent (1 .449) (.425) (.886) (1 .689) '33 -.033 -.016** -.005 -.007*** 232*" Urban (.026) (.007) (.010) (.018) (.074) [34 .076 .031 .045 .332*** -1.261*** Education (.084) (.022) (.033) (.058) (.243) '35 .663 -.021 -1.00** -.851 14.359*** Crimea (.991) (.256) (.413) (.666) (2.733) ,6, .446 -.040 -.392 -.188 3.804“ East (.676) (.174) (.265) (.460) (1.928) fl, 2668*“ -.038 853*” -2.057*** -12.032*** West (.661) (.171) (.257) (.445) (1.833) [3,, .629 .701 *** .000 -.127 1.641 Cov Part (.853) (.213) (.486) (.460) (3.661) Adjusted R2 .214 .088 .236 .235 .582 N 225 225 225 225 225 171 Table 29 (cont’d) Nat F NDP PSP RAZOM R&O Constant 1.511 7.673*** 11.988*** -.816 -1.156 (1.953) (.968) (1.754) (.822) (1.165) ,3, .522 708* 916 .252 1.610*** SMDPL (.789) (.365) (.665) (.286) (.452) ,3, 6.895*** 5.172*** 2.324 3.788*** 8.766*** incumbent (1.453) (1.317) (2.427) (1.028) (1.279) )3, -.073*** -.059*** -.210*** .053*** -.01 1 Urban (.037) (.018) (.034) (.017) (.023) p, .341*** .049 .505*** -.144*** .281*** Education (.121) (.067) (.108) (.054) (.077) P: -.560 .560 -1.742 -.776 -1.766** Crimea (1.450) (.806) (1.250) (.622) (.855) ,3, .946 .690 6.980*** 1.785*** -.053 East (.950) (.510) (.895) (.428) (.649) p, 4.765*** .300 -4.466*** .548 3.011*** West (.948) (.483) (.866) (.407) (.602) p, .022 -.783 .570 -.219 -.404 Cov Part (1.032) (.828) (1.235) (.474) (.703) Adjusted R2 .353 .177 .344 .353 .378 N 225 225 225 225 225 172 Table 29 (cont’d) S&P Bloc SDPU UNA Constant 31 958*“ 3. 502“ . 144 (3.301 ) (1.423) (.139) m 1.600 .719 .479*** SMDPL (1.148) (.537) (.063) )3, 4.085 60.205*** 343* incumbent (2.568) (3.431) (.198) 3, -.304*** -.075*** -.023 Urban (.064) (.028) (.003) 3., -.077 .466*** .022** Education (.208) (.092) (.010) 3, -9.168*** -1.886* -.173* Crimea (2.488) (1.099) (.103) ,66 -3.082* .344 -.110 East (1.678) (.729) (.074) ,3, -9.514*** 1347* .305*** West (1.605) (.705) (.070) ,3, 2.302 -.138 .577*** Cov Part (2.061) (.676) (.174) Adjusted R2 .286 .627 .491 N 225 225 225 Dependent Variable: Proportion of the vote in PR at the SMD level. The Central Region is the unit of comparison for the regional variables. Standard Errors are in parentheses. * ps.10 ** ps.05 *** ps.01 173 partisans, although no comparable data exists to evaluate the hypothesis in Russia at this time. Conclusions I have demonstrated the existence of an additional aspect of mixed systems that should encourage multiparty competition. Candidate placement in SMD affects vote outcomes in PR at the local level. This direct effect should produce an indirect effect as well: political parties should strive to place candidates in multiple SMD races in order to benefit from the “bonus” that can accrue in PR. In the empirical test, the variable SMDPL was found to be statistically significant and positive in sign in every country and for a majority of the political parties. Adding controls for rival hypotheses did not undermine confidence in the existence of the Echo Effect. Incumbency was significant in many cases, but it did not eliminate the effects of the variable SMDPL on PR vote outcomes. The same was true for the proxies for popularity, education and urbanity. Regionalism and covert partisanship had a more noticeable impact on the Echo Effect. While these controls attenuated the Echo Effect in some cases, covert partisanship was also shown to strengthen the results by recovering a lost effect for two political parties in Ukraine. Interaction between the PR and SMD components in mixed systems is at the root of an incentive structure that encourages multiparty competition. While the empirical evidence is clear, an important question remains: Do political 174 parties recognize these incentives and form their strategies based upon them? This issue will be addressed in the final chapter. 175 Chapter 6 CONCLUSIONS — PARTY STRATEGIES IN MIXED SYSTEMS The statistical analysis has established that interaction between the PR and SMD components of mixed electoral systems substantially affects party system development. While these effects have been shown to exist empirically, are parties aware of them when they form district level campaign strategies? Parties can adopt two main strategies to benefit from contamination effects, both of which should contribute to multi-candidate races in the districts. The first strategy focuses on the benefits accrued in PR through the Echo Effect. By placing candidates in as many SMD races as resources allow, the party can maximize the bonus received in PR. Moreover, it can win additional SMD seats by participating in a greater proportion of SMD contests. This go-it-a/one strategy is reasonable for parties that do not have competition for the same subset of the electorate in district races or that believe they can win seats despite the competition. If the party has a rival or rivals for the same constituency, an alternate strategy may be more effective. In the second strategy, resources are not the sole obstacle to participation in SMD contests. Rather, the party may have at least one rival for the same electoral constituency in the election. By running candidates in each district race, the two parties could split the vote between each other, reducing the total number of seats that each party obtains. Through a strategic alliance, however, both parties could maximize the number of seats gained in the legislature. 176 The dilemma can be best illustrated with an example. In this hypothetical case, the country has a non-compensatory mixed system and ten electoral districts. There are three parties in competition. Parties A and B are conservative, party C is liberal and the liberal-conservative cleavage is the only dimension of partisan competition. When each party participates in all SMD races in addition to the PR component, the system has the distribution of votes and seats found in Table 30. Table 30: Hypothetical Distribution of Votes and Seats with No Cooperation Party 01 02 D3 D4 D5 06 D7 DB 09 D10 Total Seats A PR 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 3 SMD 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 0 B PR 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 3 SMD 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 33 0 C PR 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 4 SMD 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 1 0 In the PR component, parties A and B receive three seats each and party C receives four seats. Because parties A and B compete for the same electorate (supporters of the conservative agenda), they split the local district vote. This is not problematic in the PR portion because aggregate performance determines seat allocation. The conservative parties obtain a majority of the PR seats. However, because they split the vote in SMD races, the conservative parties receive no SMD seats. Although conservatives enjoy the support of two-thirds of 177 the population, they receive a disproportionately low number of seats in the legislature. If parties A and B were to make a bargain and selectively withdraw candidates from SMD competitions, the distribution of votes and seats could be quite different (see Table 31). If Party A pulls its SMD candidates from Districts 1-5 and Party B agrees to withdraw its candidates from Districts 6-10, a strategic agreement could result in the following distribution of votes and seats (if we assume complete transferability of votes139 and that the Echo Effect is equal for both parties”): Table 31: Hypothetical Distribution of Votes and Seats with Cooperation Party D1 DZ D3 D4 D5 D6 D7 DB 09 D10 Total Seats A PR 23 23 23 23 23 43 43 43 43 43 SM D 0 0 0 0 0 66 66 66 66 66 8 PR 43 43 43 43 43 23 23 23 23 23 SMD 66 66 66 66 66 0 0 0 0 0 C PR 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 SMD 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 34 0-501030100 Although parties A and B lose some of their local PR vote by failing to run candidates in five of the districts (due to the loss of the Echo Effect), they substantially gain in the overall seat distribution. Instead of splitting the district vote in SMD and losing all seats to party C, they consolidate the conservative vote and split the SMD races between each other. While parties still gain from ‘39 If Party A does not run in a district, its supporters will choose the candidate from the other conservative party, Party B, rather than voting for the liberal party, and vice versa. 14° The bonus received in PR by running a candidate in SMD is the same in each district. 178 running candidates in as many SMD races as possible, the benefits from strategically withdrawing candidates outweigh the loss of votes in some local PR districts. With this approach, parties can also engage in partial strategic arrangements. This entails parties agreeing to cooperate in some regions of the country, but competing against one another in other districts. In choosing the optimal strategy, parties are faced with a high level of uncertainty. The environment is generally more complex than the example presented above. Often there are more than three parties in competition, parties do not know their precise level of support in the districts, they cannot be sure that voters will transfer allegiance between ideologically similar parties in cases of strategic withdrawal, and they do not know the precise effect of withdrawal in SMD on PR results. Therefore, the selection of either strategy includes an element of risk. Both strategies recognize the interactive effects of the mixed system. The first strategy attempts to exploit the effect of SMD on PR despite the fact that it could undermine SMD performance. The second strategy attempts to maximize SMD performance and take as much advantage of the effect on PR as the party can manage, constrained primarily by cooperative agreements. While these strategies exist in theory, it is unclear how consciously parties choose their strategies with contamination in mind. Because parties are often hesitant to reveal their strategies, it is difficult to confirm whether or not they are aware of contamination and how it fits into their calculations. However, based on 179 qualitative evidence, it is clear that both strategies have been utilized by parties that are aware of contamination effects. Go-It-Alone Strategy - Ukraine’s Rukh Party Many political parties were aware of the potential benefits that could accrue from contamination effects in Ukraine’s 1998 elections. lntemational organizations that advised political parties urged like-minded parties to coalesce so that resources could be pooled and parties could participate in as many SMD races as possible. In addition, by fielding a single candidate in SMD races, political movements with similar policy interests could avoid competing with one another, splitting the vote in a district and losing the seat to a party with less sympathetic policy aims.”1 Despite the efforts of advisory groups, coalition-building and resource- pooling was not very successful in Ukraine. Two years before the elections, Vyacheslav Chornovil, the leader of Rukh, indicated that the party would join forces with other centrist parties (like the Liberal Party and People’s Democratic Party) in the 1998 elections. This promise was uttered before the new rules were in place and the incentive structure of the new system was clear.142 1“ Personal conversation with Fred Bradley, Advisor for the Parliamentary Development Project in Ukraine on September 22, 1999. Mr. Bradley worked for the National Democratic Institute in Ukraine at the time of the 1998 elections. NDI advised a number of democratic parties, including Rukh, PDP, SDPU and the electoral blocs Reform and Order and Forward Ukraine. Mr. Bradley indicated that the potential interaction between the components of the mixed system was Bgesented to the parties. He suggested that it was logical that such interaction would take place. The “Law on the Election of People's Deputies of Ukraine” was initially signed in September 1997. It was subsequently amended and challenged in the Constitutional Court. The law was finally in place on March 25, 1998, four days before the actual election. 180 A member of Rukh authored the electoral rules that established a mixed system in Ukraine and designed the rules with interactive effects in mind. The author was aware that the simultaneous use of PR and SMD would generate incentives like those described by the Echo and Investment Effects.143 Rather than forming pre-electoral coalitions with similar parties, however, Rukh’s central leadership decided to compete in as many SMD races as possible in order to take advantage of the Echo Effect and to force smaller parties subsequently to merge with Rukh under terms advantageous to the party. The party even reneged on its earlier verbal agreement with other parties and mandated that local organizations place candidates in as many districts as possible regardless of the competition found in those districts (Tishchenko and Pikhovshek 1998, 282-287).144 Rukh nominated more candidates in SMD races than any other pany. Local Rukh organizations were more interested in coalition-building than the national organization. The national leadership actively discouraged local party organizations from cooperating with other parties that had similar policy agendas. For example, Rukh’s organization in Cherkaska Oblast dutifully ran candidates in most electoral districts as the national office demanded. This created some difficulties in its relationships with other democratic-minded parties and potentially damaged long-term cooperative possibilities in future elections “3 Personal conversation with Olexander Lavrynovych- Deputy in the Verkhovna Rada from Rukh, on October 11, 1999. He is also the author of the mixed system law for Ukraine. 1‘“ Rukh’s decision to run candidates in as many districts as possible was also addressed in a personal conversation with Thomas Garrett, Director of the lntemational Republican Institute in Ukraine. IRI advised parties during the 1998 campaign. 181 and the legislature.145 A similar breakdown in inter-party relationships occurred in Lviv Oblast (Tishchenko and Pikhovshek 1998, 287). By attempting to place candidates in as many districts as possible, Rukh was acting in accordance with the system’s incentive structure and the go-it- alone strategy. The proportion of Rukh-affiliated deputies elected to the Rada increased from the previous election. While 4.8% of the deputies elected in 1994 were part of Rukh, 9.6% of the deputies elected in 1998 were members of Rukh (Central Electoral Commission of Ukraine 1998). While we cannot know if adopting another strategy would have further improved Rukh’s seat allocation, Rukh’s strategy under the new mixed system improved its seat allocation compared with the previous election. Strategic Alliance - Russia’s SP8 and Yabloko Just as major parties in Ukraine recognized potential benefits from contamination effects, knowledge about the existence of these effects was widespread among the largest parties in Russia.146 In the 1999 Duma elections, some parties pursued the alternate strategy for candidate placement in SMD. Rather than running candidates in as many districts as possible, some parties chose to sacrifice potential Echo Effect benefits by making strategic arrangements with other parties to potentially improve overall seat acquisition. “5 Personal conversation with Thomas Garrett and Oksana Hasiuk of IRI-Ukraine on September 27, 1999. “6 Personal conversation with Alexey Kuzmin, Research Director of the Institute of Humanities and Political Studies on November 25, 1999. This position was also supported in conversations with Nikolai Petrov, Scholar-in-Residence at the Carnegie Moscow Center on November 25, 1999, Boris Makarenko, Deputy General Director of the Center for Political Technologies on 182 The leadership of the Union of Right Forces (SPS) and Yabloko recognized that they would share a similar electorate in most districts. While they realized that the Echo Effect could improve PR performance, they further calculated that placement of candidates in all districts was not feasible or always advantageous. By placing candidates in all districts, financial and personnel resources would be stretched to their limits and SPS and Yabloko candidates would probably split the pro-reform vote. Consequently, the leadership decided to cooperate in some regions by strategically placing candidates so that the two parties would not directly compete.147 SP8 and Yabloko agreed to cooperate in Moscow and St. Petersburg. Table 32 shows the distribution of SPS and Yabloko candidates in SMD races in these cities. Districts 191-205 are in Moscow; districts 206-213 are in St. Petersburg. In four cases, the parties withdrew candidates after registering them for SMD races. Yabloko withdrew two candidates from Moscow; SPS pulled two from St. Petersburg.148 While SPS and Yabloko candidates directly competed in seven districts, they did not oppose each other in fifteen races. In some of the districts in which they competed, one of the two parties fielded a candidate who was confident of electoral victory; competition did not undermine the likelihood of winning the November 25, 1999, and Lee Patterson, Director of the lntemational Republican Institute, Moscow. ”7 Personal conversation with Viktor Sheynis, Deputy in the Duma from Yabloko and author of Russia's mixed system on November 30, 1999. The strategic arrangement was also reported in an on-Iine journal (polit.ru 1999). OVR and the KPRF also planned to strategically withdraw candidates to improve their chances of winning district seats (Vandenko 1999). I do not know their actual level of cooperation in the election, however. "8 SPS withdrew a third candidate from St. Petersburg, but Yabloko did not have a registered candidate in that district. 183 Table 32: Nomination Patterns for SPS and Yabloko in Moscow and St. Petersburg Districts (1999)149 District SPS SPS Yabloko Yabloko Party (Registered) (Actual) (Registered) (Actual) Finished 1 91 Yes Yes No No 2 1 92 Yes Yes No No 2 193 Yes Yes Yes N050 3 1 94 No No Yes Yes 3 1 95 No No Yes Yes 4 196"51 Yes Yes Yes Yes 4;3 1 97 No No Yes Yes 4 1 98 No No Yes Yes 2 1 99151 Yes Yes Yes Yes 6;3 200 Yes Yes Yes No150 3 201151 Yes Yes Yes Yes 3;1 202 Yes Yes No No 3 203 No No No No N/A 204 Yes Yes No No 2 ..... 2 95 YesYesN°N°3 206151 Yes Yes Yes Yes 1 ;3 207151 Yes Yes Yes Yes 1;4 208"51 Yes Yes Yes Yes 32152 209 No No Yes Yes 1 210151 Yes Yes Yes Yes 4; 1 ‘53 21 1 Yes No"50 No No NIA 212 Yes No150 Yes Yes 1 21 3 Yes No150 Yes Yes 2 “9 Source: Rossiiskaya Gazeta, January 6, 2000 and [Online] http:l/www.rg.ru. 15° Change in status from registration to vote. 15‘ SPS and Yabloko competed against each other. ‘52 The SPS or Yabloko candidate may have been able to win with cooperation ‘53 Elections were invalidated. 184 district. In another case, cooperation could have yielded a victory, but both parties failed to arrange a cooperative agreement (District 208). Both SPS and Yabloko passed the 5% threshold in the PR component and received 24 and 17 deputies, respectively. In addition, five SPS candidates and four Yabloko candidates won SMD races. While Yabloko’s seat total decreased from 1995 to 1999 (from 45 to 21), the total number of seats allocated to pro-reform forces increased in the Duma.154 Conclusions Summary of Findings The analysis began with the underlying question: do mixed electoral rules affect party system development in ways not predicted by Duvergerian expectations? Maurice Duverger never considered how the combination of PR and SMD that we call mixed systems would affect party system development. His work, however, is consistently used to predict how party systems will evolve based on the electoral rules. Scholars influenced by Duverger have attempted to extend his work to new electoral systems, but have erred in their interpretations of how electoral institutions influence party system development under mixed rules. Based on traditional interpretations of Duverger’s work, scholars and institutional designers anticipated that mixed systems would behave in certain ways. Their assumptions led to unanticipated consequences. 185 If the component parts of the mixed system were independent, PR should distribute seats more proportionally than SMD. In fact, the PR component is sometimes less proportional than SMD. The most egregious example of disproportionate seat allocation in PR was in Russia’s 1995 elections when only four parties cleared the 5% threshold, “wasting” many ballots. Further, standard interpretations suggest that the threshold in PR should discourage parties that do not have a reasonable chance of passing the threshold from contesting. However, marginal parties participate in both PR and SMD in mixed systems. SMD should also provide disincentives for multi-candidate competition in the districts. Nevertheless, multi-candidate competition is common (see Table 1 in the Introduction). These unanticipated outcomes led to the empirical puzzle guiding the dissertation: why have mixed systems failed to conform with Duvergerian expectations? I proposed a possible solution: interaction between PR and SMD undermines the incentive structure at the center of Duverger’s Propositions. Contamination effects thus preclude the extension of Duvergerian expectations to mixed systems and require us to rethink how we study countries using mixed electoral rules. I analyzed party systems because they show us, at least in part, who has power in a political system. While there are many ways to assess party systems, scholars consistently measure the number of parties in competition. Because political parties and party leadership determine if and how they will participate in 15“ In June 2000, SPS and Yabloko signed an agreement to nominate a single slate of candidates in the next Duma elections. While they did not agree to merge into a single party, they promised 186 elections, understanding the incentives that mixed systems provide to parties allows us to predict how competition is likely to develop. I first showed that marginal parties - parties that receive a relatively small proportion of the vote — have incentives to participate in mixed systems. The analysis in Chapter 3 showed that the mechanical effect of mixed systems encourages participation by marginal parties. The proportionality profiles of mixed systems were distinct from the standard SMD proportionality profile and do not punish marginal parties as strongly as the mechanical effect in SMD. Next, I demonstrated that parties committing to participation in mixed systems tend to participate in both PR and SMD. The empirical evidence in Chapter 4 demonstrated that parties tend to nominate candidates in both components of the mixed system and that resources dictate, in part, how fully parties participate in SMD. It provided evidence for the Investment Effect, which contends that parties should compete in both PR and SMD because the benefits of full participation in the mixed system outweigh the benefits of participation in one component. I further illustrated that there are electoral incentives for parties to run candidates in as many SMD races as possible. The analysis in Chapter 5 provided evidence that parties can receive more votes in PR by participating in SMD. The Echo Effect should further encourage parties to nominate candidates in as many SMD races as possible, contingent upon resources and strategic arrangements with other parties. to cooperate even more closely in the next elections. 187 All of these incentives produced by the mixed system are based on the interaction between PR and SMD and contradict Duvergerian expectations. In this chapter, I provided evidence that not only do contamination effects exist in theory, but political parties in the region form their strategies with the effects in mind. Ukraine’s Rukh Party and Russia’s SPS and Yabloko understood that optimal strategies in mixed systems were a response to the entire electoral system, not only the PR or SMD components. They selected strategies that would take advantage of the strategic incentives present under mixed electoral rules. Adaptation has not been the only response to the mixed system’s unique incentive structure; some political actors have advocated change to electoral rules with more familiar and predictable consequences. Russian President Vladimir Putin has not directly attacked the mixed system, but has expressed displeasure with the current party system and distribution of power.155 Putin has shown his interest in instituting reforms to assert control over the regions156 and may also pursue institutional changes to promote a two-party system. Ukrainian President Leonid Kuchma, by contrast, has assailed the mixed system, implicating it as the cause for increased fragmentation and uncertainty in the Ukrainian parliament (Kuchma 2000). He sponsored a successful April 2000 referendum authorizing change in parliamentary structure and the electoral rules. Political leaders have recognized the power of electoral rules in shaping partisan ‘55 Various news organizations have noted President Putin’s reported preference for a two-party system (RIA Novosti 2000; Federal News Service 2000). 1 Putin instituted administrative reforms and proposed substantial changes in the Upper House’s electoral rules. These changes were designed to limit the influence of regional governors. 188 competition and have realized that mixed systems have not delivered what institutional designers promised. Extensions of the Research Although I focused on post-communist mixed systems that use non- compensatory rules to distribute seats, the results are generalizable beyond these countries. As I indicated in Chapter 1, there is substantial variation in electoral rules among mixed systems that could affect strategies that parties adopt. The analysis in the appendix provides preliminary evidence that that the findings extend to countries using different allocation rules. It also provides evidence that the effects extend to institutionalized party systems as well as new democracies.157 The dissertation focused in detail on Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine, but the analysis in the appendix shows that the findings also apply to Armenia, Germany, Japan, New Zealand, Scotland and Wales. Although it is important to more systematically address variation among mixed rules and party system types to increase confidence in the validity of the conclusions, the initial findings suggest that the results can be extended beyond the cases in the dissertation. The research also makes contributions to political science theory and the practice of institutional design. By showing that Duvergerian expectations do not apply to mixed systems, the research suggests that existing studies of mixed systems may not be valid. Moreover, it provides insight into the conditions ‘57 See Mainwaring and Scully (1995) for the criteria defining institutionalized and inchoate party systems. 189 under which Duverger’s Propositions may not operate as expected. The research also follows in the tradition of other work about the interaction of institutional factors in party system development, such as work on “coattail effects” and other aspects of executive-legislative electoral linkages (Shugart and Carey 1992; Jones 1995; Cox 1997), and provides the first extension of these principles to mixed systems. At the practical level, the findings provide useful information to institutional designers. Mixed systems have been a popular choice because of their perceived ability to facilitate compromise and solve problems of constitutional engineering and domestic politics. Because institutional designers, like political scientists, have assumed that PR and SMD should operate independently in mixed systems, this research helps explain why the goals of institutional design have not been realized in mixed systems. Further, the analysis points to features of mixed systems that designers may wish to understand when selecting electoral institutions. This dissertation also opens new areas of research based on the idea of contamination. By viewing mixed electoral systems as an entity rather than as distinct components, the research identifies properties influencing party system development that are not present in standard PR and SMD systems. This analysis, however, is only the first step in understanding the potential consequences of mixed electoral rules for party systems. Expanding the study both spatially and longitudinally will permit additional tests of the mixed system’s effects on parties. Variation in institutional rules 190 across mixed systems could alter party strategies. By increasing the number of countries studied, the effects of this variation could be better understood. Further, it is unclear if the effects found here are attributable to the inchoate party systems and small number of elections that have taken place in these systems. By collecting data over time, scholars can gain a better understanding of the dynamic properties of the incentive structure and how parties adapt to the incentives from election to election. Investigating the strategies of political parties under mixed rules using formal theory is another potential area of research. Parties may adopt different strategies to take advantage of the rules over time and across systems. Developing formal models of optimal election strategies that respond to variation in the electoral rules will allow scholars to both understand and predict how political parties behave in mixed systems. By focusing on political parties, the dissertation has downplayed the importance of individual voters. However, the strategic behavior of voters can influence party decisions. Investigating how mixed systems, and institutional variation among mixed systems, affects voter behavior will be another important contribution to understanding how political competition develops under mixed electoral rules. This analysis has also ignored the potential influence of mixed systems on legislative behavior. While studies of legislatures suggest that deputies elected through PR are more likely to conform with party expectations than those elected in SMD, this conventional wisdom probably does not apply to mixed systems 191 (see Haspel, Remington and Smith 1998). Because candidates can participate in both PR and SMD races, it is likely that parties experience a diminished capacity to command uniformity among affiliated candidates and legislators. This could have serious implications for the ability to form legislative coalitions and make policy and is thus an important question for future research. Much work is yet to be done with data from mixed electoral systems. Because the number of states using these systems continues to expand, there is an increased need to understand the potential implications for party system development. Concluding Remarks The rapid expansion of mixed systems in the 19905 no longer permits them to be considered anomalies among the world’s electoral systems. Mixed systems are used to elect legislatures at the local and national level in more than thirty countries and are present on every inhabited continent. Mixed systems have become a popular institutional choice in both new and long-standing democracies because of their perceived advantages. Under traditional assumptions of strategic incentives, mixed systems are a perfect marriage of the benefits of PR and SMD systems. Mixed systems should encourage parties to participate in elections as well as reduce the total number of competitors to a manageable level. Unfortunately, the assumption that mixed systems produce the “best of both worlds” by synthesizing the positive features of PR and SMD systems is incorrect. As I demonstrated in the dissertation, 192 electoral rules have influenced party system development in unintended ways due to contamination effects inherent in mixed systems. Mixed systems thus seem more likely to spawn Sartori’s “bastard producing hybrids” (1997a, 75) than the perfect balance of PR and SMD predicted by many institutional designers and political scientists. 193 APPENDICES 194 APPENDIX A DATA SOURCES Data for the dissertation were obtained from many sources. The primary countries under analysis are Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine. Lithuanian data were compiled from the Lithuanian Election Commission web site and were augmented with data forwarded by the Electoral Commission of Lithuania. District-level results for PR and SMD are available as are biographies of the candidates. These data were augmented by demographic information from the Soviet census of 1989. Data for the Russian Duma elections vary in quality. While data for PR results at the SMD level are not available for 1993, they are available for 1995 and 1999. Russian election data were compiled from Central Electoral Commission publications, Rossiiskaya Gazeta, and the 1989 Soviet census. Ukrainian data are comparable to Russian data. They are compiled from similar sources, including Central Electoral Commission publications and the 1989 Soviet Census. Data from other mixed systems are used to complement the analysis of Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine. Armenian electoral data were obtained from the Central Electoral Commission web site and provide basic information on the performance of parties in both portions of the system. While district results are available for the SMD races, vote outcomes in PR are only accessible at the aggregate level. In addition, information about candidates is restricted to their 195 party affiliation. Thus, Armenian results could be used for some cross-national comparison, but they were inappropriate for inclusion when evaluating the Investment and Echo Effects. German data is more detailed than Armenian data and was obtained from a scholar of German politics. District-level results of both PR and SMD components from 1953 to the present are available, but incumbency information and other pertinent data are not accessible for all elections. In addition, there are minor problems with the quality of data. The raw election counts are not available, only district level percentages. The degree to which these data have been rounded is unclear, undermining their use in some tests. Because of data quality issues, German data are used in the confirmatory analyses contained in the appendices. New Zealand data are also used in the appendices. These data were obtained from the director of the New Zealand Electoral Commission. The data include district-level results for PR and SMD races as well as information on the characteristics of the candidates in SMD. The primary source for Japanese data is Asahi Senkyo Taikan. Like the above data, aggregate results are used in cross-national comparisons. More detailed analysis of Japanese results is confined to the appendix. Data from Scotland and Wales were obtained from the BBC. They include the regional PR results and SMD results. PR results at the SMD level are not available. 196 APPENDIX B ADDITIONAL EVIDENCE FOR THE MECHANICAL EFFECT The evidence presented in Chapter 3 demonstrated that the mechanical effect in mixed systems is more forgiving to marginal parties than the mechanical effect in SMD systems. If we expand the analysis beyond the three countries in the chapter, we find additional evidence that confirms the properties of the mechanical effect in mixed systems. Figure 9 shows the proportionality profile for Armenia. There is a single outlier at 3.6 on the Y axis. The National Concord Party won a single seat in the SMD component and did not participate in PR. Because it received a small proportion of the vote in the total system but nevertheless received a seat, it is over-represented in the legislature. The remaining parties are generally clustered around unity on the Y-axis and all received less than thirty percent of the total vote. Armenia’s proportionality profile shows that many parties received proportional seat allocation in the legislature. The Japanese proportionality profile conforms most closely to the Very Late Rise profile among the countries under analysis (see Figure 10). Although the shape is similar to the Very Late Rise profile, the break even point is lower on the X axis. The Liberal Democratic Party and New Frontier Party drive the shape of the profile. These parties received 36% and 28% of the votes, respectively, and were over-represented. Most of the remaining parties received less than 197 % Seats/Vb Votes P‘ o .03 01 l 9’ o l N 01 l .N o I .3 U" l _s O I .0 01 l .0 o l Armenia B :- Standard SMD — O 30 % Votes Figure 9: Proportionality Profile for Armenia 198 60 % Seats/% Votes 3.0 2.5 ‘ N o l .5 C l 0.5 “ 0.0 3 Standard SMD Japan / /\ — 1 0 20 30 40 50 60 % Votes Figure 10: Proportionality Profile for Japan 199 15% of the vote and were under-represented. The system is more forgiving to small parties than SMD, but the functional form is similar to SMD. New Zealand’s results diverge from a standard SMD system (see Figure 11). While a large number of parties received no seats in the legislature, those that passed the barrier or won a SMD seat generally received a proportionate number of seats. Act New Zealand was slightly over-represented, with a value of 1.35 on the Y-axis and United New Zealand was slightly underrepresented, receiving a .57 on the Y-axis. The remaining parties that received seats received within .10 of 1.00 on the Y-axis. Although small parties performed poorly in New Zealand, those that received over 3% of the vote also received a proportionate seat allocation in the legislature. This is well below the threshold of 5% for representation in PR. Scottish data further confirm expectations for the mixed system (see Figure 12). Once again, we see that most parties are arrayed along the perfect proportionality line. In addition, no party received over 40% of the total vote. While the Greens are under-represented (with .43 on the Y axis), parties that received seats generally received a proportionate number of seats. As with all of the previous cases, Welsh election results also conform with expectations (see Figure 13). The distribution of seats is generally proportionate and small parties are not excluded from the legislature. All of the parties that received seats in Wales were clustered along the perfect proportionality line and the break-even point is far lower than we would expect in an SMD system. 200 % Seats/% Votes 3.0 2.5 .N o 1.5 .3 O 0.5 0.0 Standard SMD New Zealand /\ O l l I l i F 0 1 0 20 30 40 50 60 % Votes Figure 11: Proportionality Profile for New Zealand 201 % Seatsl% Votes 3.0 2.5 ‘ N o L 1.5“ 1.0'1 .0 01 1 0.0 ‘ Scotland Standard SMD 1 O 20 30 40 % Votes 50 Figure 12: Proportionality Profile for Scotland 202 60 % Seats/0A: Votes 3.0 2.5 N o 1.5 .s o 0.5 0.0 Standard SMD Figure 13: Proportionality Profile for Wales 203 Wales 0 O O l I r l l I 0 1 0 20 30 4O 50 60 % Votes Figure 14 combines all of the countries in the analysis158 into a single proportionality profile.“59 The profile crosses the perfect proportionality line under 10% on the X axis, diverging substantially from the Very Late Rise profile. Many marginally performing parties receive a proportionate seat allocation in mixed systems. All of the evidence from individual countries as well as the combined profile show that the mixed system’s mechanical effect is more forgiving to small parties than a standard SMD system. Not only has the effect proved robust in additional countries, but it is evidenced in fledgling and established democracies as well as compensatory and non-compensatory systems. ‘58 That is, I combined the countries from the main analysis (Lithuania, Russia and Ukraine) with those in the appendix (Armenia, Japan, New Zealand, Scotland and Wales) to generate a ggoportionality profile for the entire sample. Using the modified Chow Test, described in Chapter 4, I tested for structural stability. The calculated F statistic is 1.94; the critical Fug) is 5.32. The null hypothesis of structural stability cannot be rejected and the cross sections can be combined. 204 °/o Seats/%Votes 9 o 5” 01 l 9’ C 1 N 01 L 2.0 ‘ 1.5A 1.0“ All Countries 0 O Standard SMD I 30 % Votes 40 5O 60 Figure 14: Proportionality Profile for All Countries 205 APPENDIX C ADDITIONAL EVIDENCE FOR THE ECHO EFFECT The evidence presented in Chapter 5 shows that the placement of candidates in SMD positively affects PR vote outcomes at the local level. This should encourage parties to place candidates in many SMD districts, promoting multiparty competition. If we expand the analysis to other mixed systems, we also find evidence of this effect. Evidence from Germany German data allow only a basic evaluation of the Echo Effect. Because political parties quickly adapted to the mixed system and major political groups fielded candidates in almost all districts even in the initial election, this analysis is limited to the 1953 elections. Because this election was the first with separate ballots under the mixed system, German parties arguably understood the potential consequences of the mixed system as well as parties in the other countries in this dissertation. Due to the lack of information about candidates and districts in the elections, the model includes a single independent variable, SMDPL.160 The model for Germany is: 16° The data available for the 1953 elections provide information about SMD performance as a proportion of the vote received in a district. For the variable SMDPL, a district was coded "1' (a candidate was placed in the district) if the party received more than zero in that SMD race. The 206 PRPER = a + BlsMDPL + s The major German political parties (Christian Democratic Union (CDU), Social Democratic Party (SPD) and Free Democratic Party (FDP)) cannot be included in the analysis because they participated in almost all SMD contests. There is adequate variation on the independent variable for four minor parties: Bavarian Party (BP), Deutsche Partei (DP), DRP and Zentrum (Z). The OLS results provide additional support for the Echo Effect Hypothesis. The coefficient for SMDPL is statistically significant and positive in sign in three of the four cases (see Table 33). Among the parties under analysis, two (BP and 2) present a statistical problem, however. In all districts where these parties failed to run a candidate they received no PR votes.161 This substantially reduces variation on the variables of interest. The other two cases provide mixed results. Contamination is evident in the DP results. The parameter estimate of SMDPL is statistically and substantively significant for DP. The coefficient value of 8.4 for SMDPL indicates that the party receives an 8.4% increase in the local PR vote in districts where it fields an SMD candidate. SMDPL is not significant for DRP. district was coded “0” if the party received no votes in the district. While the nature of the data could introduce some coding error, the amount of error should be negligible. ‘61 It is possible that they received a very small proportion of the votes, but the data are rounded to zero. This also creates the possibility that there were SMD candidates who received a very small number of votes in the SMD component introducing some error due to coding into the 207 Table 33: OLS Results from Germany (1953) BP DP DRP z Constant 0.000 1.351 *** .970*** 0.000 (.156) (.284) (.150) (.151) ,8, 9364*“ 8.400*** .271 1569*” SMDPL (.353) (.585) (.218) (.221) Adjusted R2 .745 .460 .002 .170 N 242 242 242 242 Dependent Variable: Proportion of the vote in PR at the SMD level. Standard Errors are in parentheses. * ps.10 ** ps.05 *** ps.01 I conducted additional diagnostic tests to assess the effect of outliers on the analysis.162 There were many cases beyond three standard deviations from the mean on the dependent variable for all four parties. Removing these cases individually or as a block did not have a substantial impact on the results, however. Evidence from New Zealand Data from New Zealand also allow us to perform a limited evaluation of the Echo Effect. The model is: analysis. The only data I currently have are district-level results. I have assumed that districts in which a zero is recorded for SMD represents a district in which no SMD candidate participated. 208 PRPER = or + BISMDPL + leNC + 8 We can divide participation in the SMD component among parties in New Zealand into two categories. In the first category are parties that participated in almost all of the SMD contests. Six parties participated in virtually every district.163 Among the remaining nineteen parties, only four participated in at least 20% of the SMD contests. These are marginal parties in New Zealand politics and only one of them gained a single seat in the legislature. While it is preferable to have both major and minor parties in the analysis, lack of variation on the independent variable only allows us to include minor parties. The OLS results support the existence of the Echo Effect in New Zealand’s mixed system. The coefficient for SMDPL was not statistically significant in the Christian Coalition model, but it was significant in the other cases. While the strength of the effect may seem substantively insignificant, we must keep the relative size of the party in mind. The bonus received by the McGillicuddy Serious Party for placing a candidate in SMD is .08%. However, the party only received 29% of the total PR vote. A bonus of .08% constitutes 28% of the total PR vote. This is a substantial bonus relative to the party’s overall performance. ‘62 I did not conduct an analysis of collinearity for the German cases because there was only one independent variable. ‘63 These parties are Act New Zealand, Alliance, Labour, Natural Law Party, New Zealand First, and the New Zealand National Party. 209 Table 34: OLS Results from New Zealand (1996) cc MS PG UNZ Constant 4.197*** .219*** .198m .571*** (247) (020) (014) (058) p, .010 .081*** .145*** .366" SMDPL (.328) (.024) (.025) (.101) A. 1393*" INC (.169) Adjusted R2 -.016 .145 .338 .883 N 85 85 85 85 Dependent variable is the PR vote at the district-level. Standard Errors are in parentheses. * (33.10 ** p305 *** (33.01 The effect of the variable INCUMBENT could only be assessed in a single case in New Zealand. Among the four parties in the analysis, only United New Zealand had incumbent candidates in competition. The variable is statistically significant and its effect on PR performance is greater than that of SMDPL. However, after controlling for incumbency, the effect of SMDPL remains. Diagnostic tests for the effects of collinearity and outliers revealed no substantial impact on the OLS results. The results from New Zealand further bolster our confidence in the existence and strength of the Echo Effect. 210 Evidence from Japan The more detailed Japanese data permit a more sophisticated analysis. Once again, the dependent variable is performance in PR at the SMD level. There are three independent variables in the Japanese model. The first independent variable is SMDPL. The second is INCUMBENT. The third independent variable represents local popularity. The variable POPULARITY is coded using data from Upper House elections. The performance of parties in Upper House elections is coded at the prefecture level. If parties indeed use their knowledge of regional popularity to guide candidate placement, the effects of POPULARITY should sweep away the results attributed to SMDPL. This model tests the existence of contamination while controlling for incumbency and popularity. The LDP was not included in the Japanese analysis because there was inadequate variation in SMDPL (the LDP ran or recommended candidates in each district). However, contamination effects were assessed for six other parties. Table 35 shows the regression results for the initial model. The results show that the coefficients for SMDPL and INCUMBENT are statistically significant for all parties and the signs for all coefficients are positive. While incumbency status affects performance in the PR component, candidate placement also has an important impact on PR outcomes. Again, the coefficient values represent the bonus received by parties in PR when the independent variable is coded one. Thus, the Democratic Party of Japan (DPJ) received an additional 7.9% of the PR vote in districts where it placed a candidate on the 211 Table 35: OLS Results for Japan (1996) DPJ Jiyurengo NFP NHP SDPJ Shin. Constant 11.859*** .732*** 22.166*** 1.285*** 6.129*** 1.832*** (.379) (.104) (.708) (.080) (.141) (.091) fl, 7.9031m .802*** 5.737*** 3501*" 2.202*** 1.164*** SMDPL (.815) (.218) (.881) (.870) (.498) (.274) [32 3.208*** 15.271*** 2.838*** 8.913*** 8.893*** 5.884*** Incumbent (.887) (1.198) (.750) (.781) (.581) (1.080) Adjusted .471 .451 .238 .883 .505 .180 R N 299 232 299 153 288 299 Dependent Variable: Proportion of the vote in PR at the SMD level. Standard errors are in parentheses. * ps.10 ** ps.05 *** ps.01 SMD ballot. Moreover, it received a 3.2% bonus when the candidate was an incumbent. While the coefficient for INCUMBENT was smaller than SMD for the DPJ and New Frontier Party (NFP), it was larger for Jiyurengo, New Harbinger Party (NHP), Social Democratic Party of Japan (SDPJ) and Shinshakaito (Shin). These results show strong support for the Echo Effect. When the variable POPULARITY is added, the effect of SMD and INCUMBENT remains (see Table 36). The variable POPULARITY is a measure of performance in Upper House elections and allows us to control for the main rival hypothesis. Because of changes in the Japanese party system between the 212 Upper House elections in 1995 and Lower House elections in 1996, the variable POPULARITY could only be assessed for two parties. Only the SDPJ and NF P participated in both elections without division or merger. Results for the SDPJ show that INCUMBENT still provides the largest boost to PR performance (7.1% when a candidate is placed in SMD), but candidate placement matters both statistically and substantively. Electoral popularity also plays an important role, but provides a smaller bonus than the other two factors. Results for the NFP are similar. Although the bonus for incumbency is less than that for SMD candidate placement (2.0% versus 3.2%, Table 36: OLS Results for Japan (1996) with POPULARITY NFP SDPJ Constant 4720*” .610* (1.278) (.335) ,8, 3174*“ 2264*" SMDPL (.687) (.347) ,62 1 .995*** 7052*" Incumbent (.569) (.570) ,3; 643*” .331 *** Popularity (.043) (.019) AdjustedR2 .585 .758 N 299 286 Dependent Variable: Proportion of the vote in PR at the SMD level. Standard errors are in parentheses. * ps.10 ** p305 *** p301 213 respectively), both remain statistically significant when the additional control for popularity is added. The goodness-of-fit improves substantially for these models: the adjusted R2 improves from .51 to .76 for SDJP and from .24 to .57 for NFP when we add popularity. The analysis of collinearity and outliers did not raise any problems. The VIF was close to unity in all cases, indicating that there was only a small amount of inefficiency introduced into the model due to collinearity. Removing the outliers and reanalyzing the data did not substantially affect the results. This evidence from Germany, New Zealand and Japan shows additional support for the Echo Effect. Candidate placement in SMD affects PR performance at the local level. In sum, there is evidence of the Echo Effect in additional mixed systems, including compensatory systems and those with institutionalized party systems. 214 BIBLIOGRAPHY 215 Bibliography 1989 Census of the USSR. 1995. CD-Rom Version 1.0. East View Publications. Abramson, Paul R., John H. Aldrich, Phil Paolino and David W. Rohde. 1995. “Third-Party and Independent Candidates in American Politics: Wallace, Anderson and Perot." Political Science Quarterly. 110:349-367. Abramson, Paul R., John H. Aldrich and David W. Rohde. 1998. Change and Continuity in the 1996 Elections. Washington, DC: CQ Press. Aldrich, John. 1995. Why Parties? Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Alvarez, R. Michael and Jonathan Nagler. 1997. “When Politics and Models Collide: Estimating Models of Multiparty Elections.” Unpublished version of forthcoming manuscript, American Journal of Political Science. Ames, Barry. 1995a. “Electoral Rules, Constituency Pressures, and Pork Barrel: Bases of Voting in the Brazilian Congress.” Journal of Politics. 57:324-343. Ames, Barry. 1995b. “Electoral Strategy Under Open-List Proportional Representation.” American Journal of Political Science. 39:406-433. Asahi Shimbun Senkyo Honbu. 1997. Asahi Senkyo Taikan: Dai41kai Shugiinsosenkyo, Dai17kai Sangiintsujyosenkyo. Tokyo: Asahi Shimbunsha. BBC World Service. Scotland Elections ’99. [Online] Available http:llnews1 .thdo.bbc.co.uklhi/englishlevents/ scotland_99lthe_scottish_parliamentlnewsidfl310000/310025.stm. May 28, 1999. BBC World Service. Wales Elections ’99. [Online] Available http:llnews1 .thdo.bbc.co.uklhi/english/events/ wales_99/newsl, May 27, 1999. Barnes, Samuel H., Frank Grace, James K. Pollock, and Peter W. Sperlich. 1962. “The German Party System and the 1961 Federal Elections.” American Political Science Review. 56:899-91 4. Barrington, Lowell W. 1997. “The Geographic Component of Mass Attitudes in Ukraine.” Post-Soviet Geography and Economics. 38:601-614. 216 Bawn, Kathleen. 1993. “The Logic of Institutional Preferences: German Electoral Law as a Social Choice Outcome.” American Journal of Political Science. 37:965-989. Bilous, Artur. 1995. ll. Viborchisistemi: sviti Ukraina. [Part II. Electoral Systems: the World and Ukraine]. Kyiv: lntemational Republican Institute. Blais, André, and Louis Massicotte. 1996. “Electoral Systems.” In Lawrence LeDuc, Richard G. Niemi and Pippa Norris (eds). Comparing Democracies: Elections and Voting in Global Perspective Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage Publications. Blondel, Jean. 1968. “Party Systems and Patterns of Government in Western Democracies.” Canadian Journal of Political Science. 1:180-203 Blondel, Jean. 1969. An Introduction to Comparative Government. London: Weidenfield and Nicolson. Bogdanor, V. 1983. “Introduction.” In V. Bogdanor and D. Butler (eds) Democracy and Elections: Electoral Systems and their Consequences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brader, Ted and Joshua A. Tucker. 1998. “Congratulations, It’s a Party! The Birth of Mass Political Parties in Russia, 1993-1996.” Paper presented at the Midwest Political Science Association Conference. Budge, Ian et al. 1997. The Politics of the New Europe. New York: Addison Wesley Longman Limited. Butler, D. 1982. “Electoral Systems.” In D. Butler, H. Penniman and Austin Ranney (eds) Democracy at the Polls: A Comparative Study of Competitive National Elections. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute. Cain, B. E. 1978. “Strategic Voting in Britain.” American Journal of Political Science. 22:639-655. Calvert, Randall L. and John A. Ferejohn. 1983. “Coattail Voting in Recent Presidential Elections.” American Political Science Review. 77:407-419. Central Electoral Commission of Armenia. Election Results. [Online] Available http:l/cec.freenet.am and http:l/www.elections.aml, June 9, 1999. Central Electoral Commission of the Russian Federation. 1994. Rezul’taty golosovaniya na vyborakh v Gosudarstvennuyu Dumu po odnomandatnym izbiratel’nym okrugam. Mimeo. 217 Central Electoral Commission of the Russian Federation. 1995. Svedeniya o zaregistrirovannykh kandidatov v deputaty Gosudarstvennoy Dum y Federalnogo Sobraniya Rossiyskoy Federatsii po odnomandatnym izbiratel’nym okrugam. Mimeo. Central Electoral Commission of the Russian Federation. 1996. Vybory deputatov Gosudarstvennoy Dumy. Moscow: Ves’ Mir. Central Electoral Commission of the Russian Federation. 1998. Vybory v zakonodateln ye (predstaviteln ye) organy gosydarstvennoi v/asti sub ’ektov Rossiiskoi Federatsii 1995-1997. Moscow: Ves Mir. Central Electoral Commission of the Russian Federation. 2000. Election Results [Online]. http:l/www.fci.ru, January 20, 2000. Central Electoral Commission of Ukraine. 1998. Parlament Ukraini: Vibori-98. [The Parliament of Ukraine: Elections-98]. Volumes 1 and 2. Kyiv: Central Electoral Commission. Central Electoral Commission of Ukraine. 1999. Ukraina. Vibori-98: Dosvid, prob/emi, perspektivi. [Ukraine Elections-98: Experience, Problems, Perspectives] Kyiv: Central Electoral Commission. Chhibber, Pradeep and Kenneth Kollman. 1998. “Party Aggregation and the Number of Parties in India and the United States.” American Political Science Review. 92:329-342. Chhibber, Pradeep and Irfan Nooruddin. 2000. “Governing the Indian States: How Parties [sic] Systems Count in India.” Paper presented at the Midwest Political Science Association Conference. Christensen, Raymond V. and Paul E. Johnson. 1995. “Toward a Context-Rich Analysis of Electoral Systems: The Japanese Example.” American Journal of Political Science. 39:575-598. Clark, Terry D. 1995. “The Lithuanian Political Party System: A Case Study of Democratic Consolidation.” East European Politics and Societies. 9:41 —62. Clark, William A. 1999. “The Russian State Duma: 1993, 1995, 1999.” Problems of Post-Communism. 4623-1 1. Clark, Terry 0., Stacy J. Holscher and Lisa A. Hyland. 1999. “The LDLP Faction in the Lithuanian Seimas, 1992-1996.” Nationalities Papers. 27:227-246. Cox, Gary. 1997. Making Votes Count. New York: Cambridge University Press. 218 Cox, Gary and Matthew McCubbins. 1993. Legislative Leviathan. Berkeley: University of California Press. Craumer, Peter R. and James I. Clem. 1999. “Ukraine’s Emerging Electoral Geography: A Regional Analysis of the 1998 Parliamentary Elections.” Post- Soviet Geography and Economics. 40:1 -26. D’Anieri, Paul. 2000. “Institutional Design and the Ineffectiveness of Ukrainian and Russian Parliaments.” Paper presented at the Association for the Study of Nationalities Conference. Dahl, Robert (ed). 1966. Political Oppositions in Western Democracies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Dalton, Russell J., Scott C. Flanagan and Paul Allen Beck (eds). 1984. Electoral Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Department of Press and Information of the Federal Republic of Germany. 1998. Germaniya: Fakty. [Germany - Facts]. Hamburg: Societats Verlag. Duverger, Maurice. 1954. Political Parties: Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State. New York: Wiley. Duverger, Maurice. 1986. “Duverger's Law: Thirty Years Later.” In Bernard Grofman and Arend Lijphart (eds) Electoral Laws and their Political Consequences. New York: Agathon Press. Electoral Commission of Lithuania. Election Results. [Online] http:llrc.Irs.It/rinkimail, December 9, 1998 and June 2, 1999. Elklit, J. 1992. “The Best of Both Worlds? The Danish Electoral System 1915-20 in Comparative Perspective.” Electoral Studies. 11:189-205. Elster, Jon, Claus Offe, and Ulrich K. Pruess. 1998. Institutional Design in Post- communist Societies: Rebuilding the Ship at Sea. New York: Cambridge University Press. Epstein, Leon D. 1980. Political Parties in Western Democracies. New Brunswick: Transaction Books. Feddersen, Timothy J., Itai Sened and Stephen G. Wright. 1990. “Rational Voting and Candidate Entry Under Plurality Rule.” American Journal of Political Science. 34:1 005-1 016. 219 Federal News Service. 2000. “Remarks by Lilia Shevtsova, Carnegie Moscow Center, at 8 Breakfast of the American Chamber of Commerce in Russia (Aerostar Hotel, March 10, 2000” [Online] Available email: davidjohnson@pop.erols.com, March 13, 2000. Federal Returning Officer. 1991. The Election System in the Federal Republic of Germany. Weisbaden: mimeo. Ferejohn, John and Morris Fiorina. 1974. “The Paradox of Not Voting: A Decision Theoretic Analysis.” American Political Science Review. 68:525- 536. Fey, Mark. 1997. “Stability and Coordination in Duverger’s Law: A Formal Model of Preelection Polls and Strategic Voting.” American Political Science Review. 91 2135-147. Fish, M. Steven. 1995. “The Advent of Multipartism in Russia, 1993-1995.” Post-Soviet Affairs. 1 1 :340-383. Fish, M. Steven. 1998. “Reversal and Erosion of Democratization in the Postcommunist World.” Paper presented at the American Political Science Association Conference. Fisher, Steven L. 1973. “The Wasted Vote Thesis.” Comparative Politics. 52293-299. Gebethner, Stanislaw. 1996. “Proportional Representation Versus Majoritarian Systems: Free Elections and Political Parties in Poland, 1989-1991.” In Arend Lijphart and Carlos H. Waisman, eds. Institutional Design in New Democracies. Boulder: Westview Press. Geddes, Barbara. 1991. “Paradigms and Sand Castles in Comparative Politics of Developing Areas.” William Crotty (ed) Political Science: Looking To the Future. Evanston: Northwestern University Press. Grofman, Bernard, and Arend Lijphart (eds). 1984. Electoral Systems and Their Political Consequences. New York: Agathon Press. Grumm, J. 1958. “Theories of Electoral Systems.” Midwest Journal of Political Science. 22357-376. Gujarati, Damodar. 1995. Basic Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc. Harris, Paul. NZ Election Results. Available e-mail: GET MAIL, DATE. 220 Haspel, Moshe, Thomas F. Remington and Steven S. Smith. 1998. “Electoral Institutions and Party Cohesion in the Russian Duma.” Journal of Politics. 60:417-439. Hastie, T. J. and R. J. Tibshirani. 1990. Generalized Additive Models. New York: Chapman and Hall. Herron, Erik S. and Misa Nishikawa. 2000. “Contamination Effects and the Number of Political Parties in Mixed-Superposition Electoral Systems.” Electoral Studies. Institute of Postcommunist Societies. 1998. Pravo viboru: politiChni partii ta viborChi bloki. [The Right to Vote: Political Parties and Electoral Blocs]. Kyiv: Institute of Postcommunist Societies. International Foundation of Election Systems. 1994. Vibori v Ukraini 1994 roku. (The 1994 Ukrainian Elections]. Kyiv: IFES. International Foundation of Election Systems. 1999. Electoral Legal Framework: 1999 Parliamentary Elections in Russia. Moscow: Human Rights Publishers. lshiyama, John T. “Political Parties and Candidate Recruitment in Post-Soviet Russian Politics.” Journal of Communist Studies and Transition Politics. 15:41-69. Jesse, Eckhard. 1988. “Split-Voting in the Federal Republic of Germany: An Analysis of the Federal Elections from 1953 to 1987.” Electoral Studies. 7:109-124. Jones, Mark P. 1995. Electoral Laws and the Survival of Presidential Democracies. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press. Jones, Mark P. 1999. “Electoral Laws and the Effective Number of Candidates in Presidential Elections.” Journal of Politics. 61:171-184. Judge, David and Gabriella llonszki. 1995. “Member-Constituency Linkages in the Hungarian Parliament.” Legislative Studies Quarterly. 202161-176. Kabashima, Ikuo. 1998. Seikenkotai To Yukensha No Taidohenyo. Tokyo: Bokutakusha. Kalmanson, A. A. and Yu. F. Zudinov. 1994. “Stanovlenie mnogopartiinosti v postkommunisticheskoi Rossii.” [The Establishment of Multipartism in Post- Communist Russia] In Yu. S. Novopashin (ed. ) Politicheskiye partii! dvizheniya vostochnoi Yevropy. Moscow: Institute of Slavic and Balkan Studies. 221 Kawato, Sadafumi. 1999. “Nidai Seitosei Ni Chikazuketa Shinsenkyoseido.” Asahi Shimbun, October 11. 1996. Kiewiet, D. Roderick and Matthew McCubbins. 1991. The Logic of Delegation. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Kobayashi, Yoshiaki. 1991. Gendai Nihon No Senkyo. Tokyo, Japan: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai. Korgunyuk, Yu. G. 1999. Sovremennaya Rossiiskaya mnogopartiinost. [Contemporary Russian Multipartism] Moscow: INDEM. Krupavicius, Algis. 1998. “The Post-communist Transition and lnstitutionalization of Lithuania’s Parties.” Political Studies. 46:465-491. Kubicek, Paul. 2000. “Regional Polarisation in Ukraine: Public Opinion, Voting and Legislative Behavior.” Europe-Asia Studies. 52:273-294. Kuchma, Leonid. 2000. “About the Right and the Left.” [Online] Available http:l/www.kuchma.org/pravlevlpravlev.html, June 12, 2000. Lakatos, Imre. 1978. The Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lakeman, E and JD. Lambert. 1955. Voting in Democracies. London: Faber and Faber. Lancaster, Thomas D. and W. David Patterson. 1990. “Comparative Pork Barrel Politics: Perceptions from the West German Bundestag.” Comparative Political Studies. 22: 458-477. LaPanmbara, Joseph and Myron Weiner. 1966. Political Parties and Political Development. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Law on Elections to the Seimas. [Online] Available: http:llwww.lrs.ltl, April 4, 2000. Leys, Colin. 1959. “Models, Theories and the Theory of Political Parties.” Political Studies. 7: 1 27-1 46. Lijphart, Arend. 1984. Democracies: Patterns of Majoritarian and Consensus Government in Twenty-One Countries. New Haven: Yale University Press. 222 Lijphart, Arend. 1986. “Degrees of Proportionality of Proportional Representation Formulas.” In Bernard Grofman and Arend Lijphart Electoral Laws and Their Political Consequences. New York: Agathon Press, Inc. Lijphart, Arend. 1994. Electoral Systems and Party Systems: A Study of Twenty- Seven Democracies, 1945—1990. New York: Oxford University Press. Lijphart, Arend and Carlos H. Waisman (eds). 1996. Institutional Design in New Democracies. Boulder: Westview Press. Lipset, Seymour Martin and Stein Rokkan. 1967. Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-National Perspectives. New York: Free Press. Maguire, M. 1983. “Is There Still Persistence? Electoral Change in Western Europe, 1948-1979.” In Hans Daalder and Peter Mair (eds) Western European Party Systems: Continuity and Change. London: Sage. Mainwaring, Scott and Timothy R. Scully. 1995. Building Democratic Institutions: Party Systems in Latin America. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Massicotte, Louis and André Blais. 1999. “Mixed Electoral Systems: A Conceptual and Empirical Survey.” Electoral Studies. 18: 341 -366. McFauI, Michael, Nikolai Petrov and Andrey Ryabov with Elizabeth Reisch (eds). 1999. Primer on Russia’s 1999 Duma Elections. Washington: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Miyake, Ichiro. 1989. Tohyo Kodo. Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai. Mizusaki, Tokifumi and Hiroki Mori. 1998. “Tokuhyo Data Kara Mita Heiritsusei No Mekanizumu.” Senkyo Kenkyu 1998. Moe, Terry M. and Michael Caldwell. 1994. “The Institutional Foundations of Democratic Government: A Comparison of Presidential and Parliamentary Systems.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics. 150:171-195. Moraski, Byron and Gerhard Lowenberg. 1999. “The Effect of Electoral Thresholds on the Revival of Former Communist Parties in East-Central Europe.” Journal of Politics. 61 :151-170. Moser, Robert G. 1997. “The Impact of Parliamentary Electoral Systems in Russia.” Post-Soviet Affairs. 13:284-302. Moser, Robert G. 1999a. “Electoral Systems and the Number of Parties in Postcommunist States.” World Politics. 51: 359-384. 223 Moser, Robert G. 1999b. “Independents and Party Formation: Elite Partisanship as an Intervening Variable in Russian Politics.” Comparative Politics. 31 :147-165. Neto, Octavio Amorim and Gary W. Cox. 1997. “Electoral Institutions, Cleavage Structures, and the Number of Parties.” American Journal of Political Science. 41 :149-1 74. Nie, Norman, Sidney Verba and John Petrocik. 1976. The Changing American Voter. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Nohlen, D. 1984. “Two Incompatible Principles of Representation.” In Arend Lijphart and Bernard Grofman (eds) Choosing an Electoral System. New York: Praeger. NAU. 1999. NormativniAkti Ukraini. [CD-Rom]. Kyiv: NAU. North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ordeshook, Peter and Olga Shvetsova. 1994. “Ethnic Heterogeneity, District Magnitude and the Number of Parties.” American Journal of Political Science. 38:100-123. Palfrey, Thomas. 1989. “A Mathematical Proof of Duverger’s Law.” In Peter C. Ordeshook, ed., Models of Strategic Choice in Politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Pedersen, MN. 1983. “Changing Patterns of Electoral Volatility in Eur0pean Party Systems; 1948-1977: Explorations in Explanation.” In Hans Daalder and Peter Mair (eds) Western European Party Systems: Continuity and Change. London: Sage. Petrenko, Viktor, Olga Mitina and Ruth Brown. 1995. “The Semantic Space of Russian Political Parties on a Federal and Regional Level.” Europe-Asia Studies. 47:835-857. Pikhovshchek, Vyacheslav, Svitlana Kononchuk, Yuliya Tishchenko and Vasil Ganzha. 1999. Politichniy protsess v Ukraini: Suchasni tendentsii ta inston'chniy kontekst. [The Political Process in Ukraine: Current Tendencies and Historical Context] Kyiv: Agency “Ukraine.” Polit.ru. Pravaya odnomandatnaya koalitsiya po-prezhnemu zhiznesposobna. [The Right Single Member District Coalition is Viable as Before] [Online] Available http:llwww.politm/documents/154869.html, December 16, 1999. 224 Rae Ree Rel RI/ RiI< Rc Rt Rae, Douglas W. 1971. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws. New Haven: Yale University Press. Reed, Steven R. 1990. “Structure and Behavior: Extending Duverger’s Law to the Japanese Case.” British Journal of Political Science. 20:335-356. . 1999. “Strategic voting in the 1996 Japanese general election.” Comparative Political Studies. 32:257-270. Remington, Thomas F. and Steven S. Smith. 1996. “Political Goals, Institutional Context, and the Choice of an Electoral System: The Russian Parliamentary Election Law.” American Journal of Political Science. 40: 1253-1279. RIA Novosti. 2000. “Kremlin Returns to Once-Malfunctioned [sic] Idea of Bipartisanship to Put an End to Political Turmoil.” [Online] Available email: davidjohnson@pop.eroIs.com, April 13, 2000. Riker, William H. 1982. “The Two-Party System and Duverger’s Law: An Essay on the History of Political Science.” American Political Science Review. 76:753-766. . 1986. “Duverger’s Law Revisited.” In Bernard Grofman and Arend Lijphart, eds. Electoral Laws and their Political Consequences. New York: Agathon Press. Rokkan, Stein. 1968. “The Growth and Structuring of Mass Politics in Smaller European Democracies.” Comparative Studies in Society and History. 10:173-210. Rose, Richard. 1983. “Elections and Electoral Systems: Choices and Alternatives.” In V. Bogdanor and D. Butler (eds) Democracy and Elections: Electoral Systems and their Consequences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Rose, Richard, Evgeny Tikhomorov and William Mishler. 1997. “Understanding Multi-Party Choice: The 1995 Duma Election.” Europe-Asia Studies. 49:799- 823. Rossiiskaya Gazeta. January 17, 1996. Rossiiskaya Gazeta. January 24, 1996. Rossiiskaya Gazeta. January 6, 2000. 225 Rossiiskaya Gazeta. Registration of Candidates. [Online] http:llwww.rg.ru, December 12, 1999. Rossiiskiye regiony nakanunye vyborov-95. 1995. Moscow: Yuridicheskaya Literatura. Sartori, Giovanni. 1968. “Political Development and Political Engineering.” In J.D. Montgomery and AC. Hirschman (eds) Public Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. . 1976. Parties and Party Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press. . 1986. “The Influence of Electoral Systems: Faulty Laws or Faulty Method?” In Bernard Grofman and Arend Lijphart (eds). Electoral Systems and Their Political Consequences. New York: Agathon Press. . 1997a. Comparative Constitutional Engineering. New York: New York University Press. . 1997b. “Electoral Reform and Change in Party Systems.” Presented at the International Forum for Democratic Studies. Washington, DC: National Endowment for Democracy. Schlesinger, Joseph A. 1991. Political Parties and the Winning of Office. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1986. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions.” In Herbert F. Weisberg (ed.). Political Science: The Science of Politics. New York: Agathon Press. Sheynis, Viktor. 1999. Za chestnye vybory. [For Honest Elections] Moscow: Center of Political and Economic Research. Shively, W. Phillips. 1970. “The Elusive Psychological Factor: A Test for the Impact of Electoral Systems on Voters” Behavior.” Comparative Politics. 32115-125. Shugart, Matthew S. 1994. “Minorities Represented and Unrepresented.” In Wilma Rule and Joseph Zimmerman (eds) Electoral Systems in Comparative Perspective: Their Influence on Women and Minorities. Westport: Greenwood. Shugart, Matthew, and John M. Carey. 1992. Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 226 Sh Si: Sli Sn Shvetsova, Olga. 1999. “A Survey of Post-Communist Electoral Institutions: 1990-1998.” Electoral Studies. 18: 397-409. Siavelis, Peter and Arturo Valenzuela. 1994. “Electoral Engineering and Democratic Stability: The Legacy of Authoritarian Rule in Chile.” In Arend Lijphart and Carlos H. Waisman, eds. Institutional Design in New Democracies. Boulder: Westview Press. Slider, Darrell. 1996. “Elections to Russia’s Regional Assemblies.” Post-Soviet Affairs. 12:243-264. Smyth, Regina. 1997. Building Democracy by Winning Votes? Candidates and Parties in Transitional Russia. Dissertation: Duke University. Spafford, D. 1972. “Electoral Systems and Voters’ Behavior: Comment and a Further Test.” Comparative Politics. 52129-134. Taagepera, Rein and Markku Laakso. 1980. “Proportionality Profiles of West European Electoral Systems.” European Journal of Political Research. 8:423-446. Taagepera, Rein, and Matthew Soberg Shugart. 1989. Seats and Votes: The Seats and Determinants of Electoral Systems. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Tishchenko, Yu. and V. Pikhovshek. 1998. Vibori-98: Yak I kogo mi obirali. [Elections-98: How and Who We Elected]. Kyiv: Agency “Ukraine.” Turner, Arthur W. 1993. “Postauthoritarian Elections.” Comparative Political Studies. 26:330-349. Vandenko, Igor. 1999. “KPRF - OVR soyuz nerushimiy na printsipakh vsevlastiya.” [The KPRF — OVR Union is Unbroken in the Principles of Full Power] Novye Izvestiya. December 9, 1999. Vasilyev, VI. and A.E. Postnikov. 1995. Vybory v Gosudarstvennuyu Dumu. [Elections to the State Duma] Moscow: BEK. Wada, Junichiro. 1995. “Shosenkyoku Hireidaihyo Heiritsusei Ni Kansuru Geimuronteki Ichikousatsu.” Senkyo Kenkyu. No.10 1995. Wattenberg, Martin P. 1990. The Decline of American Political Parties 1952- 1988. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. 227 White, Stephen, Richard Rose and Ian McAIlister. 1997. How Russia Votes. Chatham: Chatham House Publishers. White, Stephen, Matthew Wyman and Olga Kryshtanovskaya. 1995. “Parties and Politics in Post-Communist Russia.” Communist and Post-Communist Studies. 28:183-202. White, Stephen, Matthew Wyman and Sarah Oates. 1997. “Parties and Voters in the 1995 Russian Duma Elections." Europe-Asia Studies. 49:767-798. Whitten, Guy D. and Harvey D. Palmer. 1996. “Heightening Comparativists’ Concern for Model Choice: Voting Behavior in Great Britain and the Netherlands.” American Journal of Political Science. 40:231-260. Wildavsky, Aaron. 1959. “A Methodological Critique of Duverger’s Political Parties.” Journal of Politics. 21 :303-318. Wyman, Matthew, Bill Miller, Stephen White and Paul Heywood. 1994. “The Russian Elections of December 1993.” Electoral Studies. 13:254-271. 228 II