.z, . 2.3 .D.‘ $.42 9.5. . in an at . . _ . ‘ ... xiv 4.. .u: d... 39.3.. r. . i}: .2, aka.” . $4“? :r Tully; '/ CCM This is to certify that the dissertation entitled The Effects of Taxes on Foreign Direct Investment in the United States presented by Taejoo Kim has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph . D. degree in Economics Mfwmx Major professor Date ’0 74/,” Zoof MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 uneasy "' Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DALE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE \ ,1 $151002??? ()9 SEP 1 821392 «6/ to 6/01 cJCIRC/DateDuep65-p. 15 THE EFFECTS OF TAXES ON FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN THE UNITED STATES By Taejoo Kim A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2001 ABSTRACT THE EFFECTS OF TAXES ON FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN THE UNITED STATES By Taejoo Kim The main objective of this dissertation is to analyze the effects of US. taxation on foreign direct investment in the US. Specifically, this dissertation tries to provide empirical answers to some questions regarding the relationship between F D1 in the US. and the US. effective corporate tax rate: (a) what is the qualitative response of F D1 in response to a change in the effective tax rate?, (b) how does the foreign investor country’s double-taxation-relief system affect the response of F D1 in the US. to the US. effective tax rate?, (c) is the average effective tax rate or the marginal effective tax rate the better explanatory variable for FDI behavior?, and ((1) what are the responses of acquisition-type F DI and establishment-type FDI to both the average and the marginal effective tax rate? The estimation results indicate that overall foreign investment decreases in response to an increase in the US. average effective tax rate, and that multinationals from countries with worldwide system do not appear to adjust their investment, but multinationals from countries with territorial system reduce their investment in the US. in response to an increase in the US average effective tax rate. These results are consistent with the Traditional View, but do not conform to the New View. The industrial organization theory suggests that F D1 is closely related to market imperfections, and FDI is a result of highly strategic decision-making of a multinational corporation. Also, most F D1 is accounted for by acquisition of existing US. firms. Therefore, FDI is not expected to respond to the marginal effective tax rate, which is based on the perfect-competition assumption and measures the tax burden of a new investment project. My estimation results appear to support this hypothesis. Another estimation result of mine indicates that establishment-type F DI does not respond to a change in either the average effective tax rate or the marginal effective tax rate. I explain this result with the composite feature of establishment-type FDI: it is a new investment and it is a mode of FDI. On balance, this dissertation does not support the New View. I think the problems of the New View arise from its assumptions: perfect capital mobility among countries and among assets. Perfect capital mobility means that every adjustment process takes place immediately. So, in the world of the New View, the economy is always in the equilibrium state. However, in the case of direct investment, capital seems to move slowly in response to a change in the relative tax rates between countries and between assets. These capital movements, in turn, lead to changes in asset prices and in the pretax returns of the assets. That is, the change in the pre-tax rate of return in response to a change in tax rate is the result of the process of capital movements. But, the New View thinks that every adjustment process occurs immediately, and the price and the pretax return change immediately in response to a tax change. And then capital (direct investment) moves again in response to these changes in asset price. The problems of the New View seem to arise from this misunderstanding. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS Many people helped to make this dissertation possible and I would like to thank some of them. First, I would like to express my gratitude and sincere appreciation to my advisor, Professor Charles L. Ballard, for his guidance, advice, and encouragement. Without his invaluable advices and encouragement, the completion of this dissertation would not have been possible. I would also like to thank other members of my committee, Professor Leslie Papke and Jeffrey Wooldridge for their valuable comments. In addition, I would like to thank Korean government (Ministry of Finance and Economy) for giving me an opportunity to study abroad. I thank my parents and parents-in-law for their continuing love and support. And most of all I wish to thank my wife Sooyeon Lee and two sons, Konhyung and Sangwoo. Last four years were in many ways harder for them than those were for me. I want to thank them for their patience, understanding, and love. iv TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ........................................................................ vii LIST OF FIGURES ....................................................................... ix CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION ........................................................................ 1 1. Foreign Direct Investment in the United States ................................. 1 2. Economic Effects of F DI ......................................................... 2 3. FDI and Taxes ....................................................................... 4 CHAPTER 1] LITERATURE REVIEW AND DATA ISSUES ..................................... 9 1. Literature Review ................................................................... 9 2. Data Issues ........................................................................... 14 2.1. FDI Data ........................................................................ 14 2.2. Data on the Effective Tax rates .............................................. 18 CHAPTER III THE NEW VIEW ON TAXES AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT ...... 24 1. The New View ....................................................................... 24 2. Problems of the New View ......................................................... 26 3. Problems in the New View’s Empirical Analysis ................................ 30 3.1. Problems of the Average Effective Tax Rates by Tax Analysts ......... 31 3.2. Problems of the Way the New View uses Tax Analysts’ Data ........... 34 3.3. Replication Results of Swenson’s Estimation .............................. 39 4. Summary ............................................................................. 43 CHAPTER IV OVERALL U.S. TAX EFFECT ON FDI IN THE US. ............................... 45 1. Tax Consequences of the US. Source Income of Foreign Investors ......... 45 2. Empirical Model Specification .................................................... 46 3. Data .................................................................................... 51 4. Estimation Results ........................................... -. ....................... 55 CHAPTER V FDI IN THE US. AND THE INTERNATIONAL TAX SYSTEM OF THE INVESTOR COUNTRY ....................................................... 61 1. Overview of the International Taxation System ................................. 61 2. The Response of FDI in the US by International Tax Regime ............... 62 3. Empirical Results of Previous Studies ............................................ 63 4. Model Specification and Data ...................................................... 65 5. Estimation Results .................................................................... 73 CHAPTER VI TYPES OF FDI AND EFFECTIVE TAX RATES .................................... 80 1. FDI and the Measures of Effective Tax Rates .................................... 81 1.1. Characteristics of FDI ......................................................... 81 1.2. Composition of FDI ............................................................ 85 2. Establishment FDI and the Effective Tax Rates ................................. 90 2.1. Incentives to the Establishment F DI ......................................... 92 2.2. Empirical Analysis ............................................................. 95 CHAPTER VII CONCLUSION ........................................................................... 100 APPENDIX: CALCULATION OF MARGINAL EFFECTIVE TAX RATE 107 1. Model .................................................................................. 107 2. Tax Variables ......................................................................... 110 3. Expected Inflation Rate ............................................................. 117 4. Other Variables ....................................................................... l 19 5. Calculation ............................................................................ 122 REFERENCES .............................................................................. 126 vi LIST OF TABLES Table 1. Summary of Empirical Studies ................................................ Table 2. Replication Result of Swenson (1994)‘s Table 3 ........................... Table 3. Illustration of Swenson’s Calculation of the AETR for Each Industry ................................................................. Table 4. Replication Result of Swenson‘s Industry-level Estimation ............... Table 5. Replication Result of Swenson‘s Country-level Estimation ................ Table 6. FDI in the US. by Industry: 1979-1996 ....................................... Table 7. Average Effective Tax Rates by Industry .................................... Table 8. Marginal Effective Tax Rates by Industry ................................... Table 9. Test Results (Total FDI on Measures of the Effective Tax Rate) ......... Table 10. Table 1 1. Table 12. Table 13. Table 14. Table 15. Table 16. Table 17. Table 18. FDI by Industry and the Average Effective Tax Rate ..................... F DI by Industry and the Marginal Effective Tax Rate ..................... Home Country’s International Tax System and After-tax Return ....... F DI in the US by Major Investor Countries: 1979-1996 ................ FDI from Territorial Countries and the AETR ............................. FDI from Territorial Countries and the METR ............................ FDI from Worldwide Countries and the AETR ............................ F DI from Worldwide Countries and the METR ........................... Acquisition FDI and the AETR .............................................. vii 13 36 37 41 44 52 53 54 55 58 60 63 67 74 75 78 79 88 Table 19. Acquisition F DI and the METR ............................................. 89 Table 20. Establishment FDI and the AETR .......................................... 98 Table 2]. Establishment FDI and the METR .......................................... 99 Table A—1. Corporate Income Tax Rates ............................................... 111 Table A-2. Investment Tax Credit Rates ............................................... 112 Table A-3. Depreciation Methods ....................................................... 116 Table A-4. Comparison of the Expected and Actual Inflation Rates ............... 1 18 Table A-5. Economic Depreciation Rates .............................................. 120 Table A-6. Asset Lifetimes ............................................................... 121 Table A-7. Asset Share .................................................................... 123 Table A-8. Capital Stock Share by Industry ............................................ 124 viii LIST OF FIGURES Figure I. MacDougall Model ............................................................. Figure 2. Foreign Direct Investment in the US: 1979-1996 ........................ Figure 3. The Avearge Effective Tax Rates ............................................ Figure 4. Comparison of the Marginal Effective Tax Rates ......................... Figure 5. Comparison of the AETR of Tax Analysts and that of Tax Foundation Figure 6. FDI in the US. and the US. Balance on Current Account ............... Figure 7. Effective Corporate Tax Rates in the US: 1979-1996 .................... Figure 8. The US. Balance on Current Account with Seven Major Investor Countries ........................................................................ ix I7 21 22 33 50 68 69 CHAPTER I INTRODUCTION 1. Foreign Direct Investment in the United States Direct investment implies that a person has a lasting interest in and a degree of influence over the management of a business enterprise in another country. For the United States, ownership or control of 10 percentl or more of an enterprise’s voting securities is considered evidence of such a lasting interest or degree of influence over management. Thus, foreign direct investment (F D1) in the United States is defined as “the ownership or control, directly or indirectly, by one foreign person of 10 percent or more of the voting securities of an incorporated US. business enterprise or the equivalent interest in an unincorporated US. business enterprise”2. Any investment that is not direct investment by this definition is considered portfolio investment. In 1997, outlays of foreign direct investors to acquire or establish businesses in the US. were $69.7 billion, about 8.1% of domestic nonresidential fixed investment. Foreign investors can undertake FDI in the US by acquiring shares of existing US. firms, or by establishing new subsidiaries or branches. Quantitatively, acquisition is ' The lO-percent criterion is somewhat arbitrary, and may understate or overstate foreign control. However, Graham and Krugrnan (1995) suggest that, in the aggregate, the danger of overstatement and understatement is not that large. They point out that, on average. foreign parents controlled 77.5 percent of their US. afiiliates in 1991. 2 Quijano (1990), p. 29. the more important route of F DI. Figure 2 in Chapter 2 shows that the acquisition type of FDI accounts for over 80 percent of total FDI. The choice between acquisition and new establishment depends on many strategic considerations. The strategic considerations and the reason why foreign investors prefer the acquisition route will be discussed in Chapter 6. 2. Economic Effects of FDI According to the neoclassical theory of the effects of F DI (MacDougall model3), FDI leads to an increase in the output of the world as a whole. The gain from FDI is shared by both the home country (investor country) and the host country (investee country). In a world of perfect competition and no externalities, foreign direct investment equalizes the marginal productivities of capital of both the investor and investee countries. The efficiency in the use of capital improves, and the total output of the world increases. The argument of the neoclassical model is easily explained by Figure 14. In Figure 1, the vertical axes measure the marginal product of capital in the investor country (MPKI) and the investee country (MPKZ) and the horizontal axis measures the total capital endowment of the world. The lines ee ’ and dd’ represent the marginal productivity schedule of the investor country and the investee country, respectively. Before FDI takes place, the investor country produces Olebc of output with 3 MacDouga11(l960). ‘ Caves (1996), p. 194. 01c capital in combination with the given amount of labor, and the investee country (host country) produces Ogdac with 02c capital. The price of capital is 01R] in the investor country, which is lower than that in the investee country Osz. Now fc amount of FDI flows from the investor country to the investee country, and the marginal productivity of capital is equalized between the two countries at OR = 02R. As a result of FDI, the output is Olegf in the investor country and Ogdgf in the investee country. Compared with the total output before F DI, total world output is increased by the triangle abg. The output of the investor country is decreased byfgbc, but as a return to FDI the investor country receives fghc. The investor country enjoys greater national income than before FDI. Similarly, the investee country enjoys a net increase of national income agh. Figure 1. MacDougall Model MPK1 d MPK2 e (1 R2 R g h R R1 / b d ’ e 0/ C 02 Of course, the MacDougall model cannot capture all the economic effects of F DI, because it is based on several strong assumptions: perfect competition, perfect capital 3 mobility, no extemalities, and no consideration of time (it is a static model). As a matter of fact, FDI has an effect on the quantity and quality of employment, technology diffusion, balance of payments, and other variables such as national security. In reality. most debates on the effects of FDI concentrate on these external effects. Advocates of FDI argue that FDI creates huge job opportunities in the US, or that FDI brings good technology into the US and stimulates domestic R&D efforts, or that capital inflow through F DI improves the balance of payments. In contrast, critics of FDI argue that foreign firms tend to obtain more of their production inputs from abroad than US. firms, and that the resulting reduced demand for the products of domestic suppliers costs the US jobs and worsens the US. trade balance. They also argue that R&D by foreign- controlled firms is skewed toward less challenging application-oriented technologies, rather than more basic and scientific technologies. Due to the nature of the extemalities, there is not much evidence on these arguments5 . Graham and Krugman (I 995) review these issues and conclude that F D1 in the US. is not a bad thing on balance. 3. F DI and Taxes There are a variety of reasons why multinational corporations (MNCs) invest abroad: acquiring particular resources (labor, natural resources, technological capability, or management skill) at a lower cost, supplying goods and services to markets in the host 5 For more detailed discussion about the debates and empirical evidence, see Graham and Krugman (1995, chapter 3-6). country or in adjacent markets, seeking benefits from economies of scale and scope, or promoting long-term strategic objectives (such as. advancing international competitiveness by acquiring the assets of foreign corporations)6. In addition to these factors, the host-country tax system also potentially affects the attractiveness of investment by foreigners. There are two different views on how foreign direct investment responds to tax variables: the traditional “choice between alternative investment locations” view and the new “asset competition” view. While the traditional view argues that FDI in the US. should respond negatively to an increase in the US. tax rate, the new view argues that F D1 in the US. should respond positively to an increase in the US tax rate. According to the “choice between alternative investment locations” view, foreign investors compare the after-tax rate of return in the US (Rus[1-Tus]) and that in the home country (RH[I-TH]), where R, is the pre-tax return in a country, and Ti denotes the effective tax rate in a country. Foreign investors decide to undertake investment in the location with the higher after-tax rate of return. In this view, an increase in the US. tax rate reduces the after-tax rate of return, and leads to a decrease in FDI in the US. (that is, TusT ——> FDI I). Hartman (1984) and Boskin and Gale (1987) support this view. The “asset competition” view criticizes the “choice between alternative investment locations” view in that it ignores the possibility that the pre-tax rate of return may be affected by the change in tax rate. In the asset competition view, competition for tax- favored assets causes the relative price of the tax-advantaged assets to rise, and this means that the pre-tax rate of return of the tax-favored assets decreases. Therefore, an ‘5 Dunning (1992), pp. 56-61. increase in the US tax rate decreases the price of US assets, and increases the pre-tax rate of return on the US assets. Since foreign investors from countries with a territorial tax system7 do not pay taxes on foreign income to their home country, they receive the full U.S. after-tax return (Rusll-TUSD. Firms from countries with a worldwide tax system pay taxes to their home country and get a foreign tax credit (RU5[1-TH]), so in general, their total taxes are not affected by the US. tax changes. However, according to the asset competition view, firms from countries with a territorial tax system are not greatly affected by an increase in the US tax rate, but worldwide firms increase their investment in response to an increase in the US. tax rate. Swenson argues that an increase in the US. tax rate leads to an increase in the US. pretax rate of return. These changes do not affect much the investment incentive of territorial firms. but they make worldwide firms increase their investment in the US. Accordingly, total F D1 in the US, which is the sum of FDI from the territorial countries and FDI from the worldwide countries, should respond positively to the US. tax rate. The asset competition view is addressed in depth in Chapter 3. The main purpose of this paper is to analyze the effects of US taxation on F DI in the US. More specifically, this paper tries to provide empirical answers to some 7 Multinationals are subject to taxation by their home countries, and by their host countries. To relieve the double-taxation problem, each country adopts either a “worldwide” system or a “territorial” system. Under the worldwide system, multinationals get credits for taxes paid to foreign countries, but under the territorial system, multinationals do not have to pay taxes on foreign earnings. The US, the UK, and Japan adopt the worldwide system. France, Germany, Canada, and the Netherlands adopt the territorial system. I This statement is based on the assumption that the rate of taxation of the worldwide country is greater than that ofthe U.S. questions regarding the relationship between FDI in the US and the US effective corporate tax rate: (a) Does FDI in the US respond positively or negatively to an increase in the US effective corporate tax rate measure? (b) How does the foreign investor country’s double-taxation-relief system affect the response of FDI in the US. to the US effective corporate tax rate? (c) Is the average effective tax rate or the marginal effective tax rate the better explanatory variable for FDI behavior? (d) What is the response of establishment-type F DI to both the average effective tax rate and the marginal effective tax rate? This dissertation is organized as follows. In Chapter 2, I review the relevant literature and discuss the data issues. The argument of the New View and the empirical analysis of Swenson (1994) are reconsidered in Chapter 3. In Chapters 4 and 5, I investigate the effects of US. effective corporate tax rate on F D1 in the US, as well as the effects of the foreign investor country’s international tax system on FDI in the US. This paper is different from Hartman (1984), Boskin and Gale (1987), and Slemrod (1990), in that I use acquisition and establishment data, while they use capital/low data. Even though I use a different F DI data set, I get results that are similar to those of Hartman, Boskin and Gale, and Slemrod. Also, this paper is different from Swenson (1994) in that my calculation of the average effective tax rates is different from hers. I get opposite results from those of Swenson (1994), even though I use the same FDI data. I explain the data on FDI and the effective tax rates in Chapter 2. In Chapter 6, this paper compares the average effective tax rate and the marginal effective tax rate in explaining F DI behavior. Also in Chapter 6, I investigate the response of establishment-type FDI to 7 the average and the marginal effective tax rate. Finally, Chapter 7 provides a conclusion. CHAPTER II LITERATURE REVIEW AND DATA ISSUES 1. Literature Review Early studies on the effects of taxation on FDI in the US concentrate on analyzing the relationship between capital inflow and measures of the after-tax rate of return. Hartman (1981, 1984), the first contribution, analyzes the effect of taxes on FDI, using annual capital flow data9 for the years 1965 - 1979. He distinguishes FDI financed by retained earnings from FDI financed by funds transfers from parent firms, and estimates separate equations for these two types of F DI. He uses the after-tax rate of return realized by foreign investors, the after-tax rate of return on overall US. capital, and the tax rate on US. capital owned by foreigners relative to the tax rate on US. capital owned by US. investors as explanatory variables. He excludes explicitly the home-country tax rate as an explanatory variable, based on the arguments of Hartman (1985)”). He finds a positive 9 There are two different kinds of FDI data available: one is the acquisition and establishment data, and the other is the direct investment capitalflows data (balance-of-payments data). The capital flow data consist of the equity capital. the intercompany debt between US. affiliates and their parents, and the reinvested earnings. If a foreign affiliate borrows in the US. in order to buy a machine, this transaction will not appear in these data. For more detailed explanation for the capital flow data, see section 2.2. '0 Hartman (1985) argues that the home country’s rate of tax on foreign source income and the presence or absence of a foreign tax credit should be irrelevant to a mature foreign subsidiary’s investment and dividend decision. He compares after—tax rates of return from two alternative investment decisions (reinvestment or immediate repatriation) of a mature foreign subsidiary. The parent firm’s after-tax rate of return from reinvestment is [(l-t)/(1-t*)][1+r*(l-t*)], and that from repatriation is [(1-t)/(l-t*)][1+r(l-t)], where t is tax rate, r is rate of return, and * stands for a host-country variable. Therefore, the home-country system of deferring taxes and providing a credit for host-country tax payment (worldwide system) induces 9 effect of the after-tax rate of return on both types of FDI, and the effect is much stronger for FDI financed by retained earnings. He also finds a negative effect of the relative tax term on F DI. These results suggest that FDI (especially FDI by retained earnings) responds negatively to the US. average tax rate. Boskin and Gale (1987) reestimate Hartman’s (1984) equations, using updated series for the tax rate and the rate of return. Their qualitative results are consistent with those of Hartman (1984), even though the estimated elasticities of F DI to the rate of return are somewhat lower. They also try some different model specifications and different sample periods. They conclude that although the results are somewhat sensitive to sample periods and model specification, the qualitative conclusions of Hartman (1984) are fairly robust. Young (1988) uses revised data on foreign direct investment and rate of return for the sample period 1953-1984 to estimate equations similar to those of Hartman. He modifies the Hartman model by including the lagged dependent variable and US. GNP as explanatory variables. His results indicate that foreign direct investment in the US. through retained earnings appears to be more sensitive to tax rates than foreign direct investment through transfer of new funds. This is consistent with the findings of Hartman. Slemrod (1990) points out that previous studies ignored the possibility that FDI could be affected by home-country taxationl 1, and did not consider nontax determinants multinational firms to invest abroad up to the point at which the after-foreign-tax return available abroad equals the available domestic after-tax return. He explains that this conclusion arises from the unavoidable nature of the tax for a firm with subsidiary earnings. ” Slemrod (1990) points out that Hartman‘s (1985) argument does not apply to an immature subsidiary’s investment (FDI financed by funds transfers from the parent company), but only applies to a mature IO of F DI. Therefore, he investigates the effect of both US. and home-country taxation on FDI in the US. Firstly, he changes the model specification by introducing a marginal effective tax rate as a tax variable. rather than an average effective tax rate, and by including other explanatory variables, such as the real exchange rate. The results are that the US. effective tax rate has a negative effect on total FDI and FDI financed by transfer of funds, but not on investment from retained earnings. Secondly, Slemrod disaggregates FDI data by the major investing countries. It is expected that investors from territorial- system countries would respond sensitively to the US. marginal effective tax rate, but that for investors from worldwide-system countries, the US tax rate would be a less crucial factor. However, Slemrod‘s estimation results generally do not support this prediction. About the effect of the home-country taxation on FDI in the US, it is expected that FDI from territorial countries should be positively related to the home- country tax rate. But transfers of funds from worldwide countries should have a less positive relation to the home-country tax rate, and retained earnings from those countries should be unaffected. The regression results do not support these predictions. Slemrod concludes that these results suggest that home-country taxation does not have much effect on FDI in the US. Auerbach and Hassett (1993) distinguish acquisition-type FDI from establishment- type F DI. They argue that establishment FDI could be affected by the marginal effective tax rate, and that acquisition FDI should be affected primarily by the laws regarding mergers and acquisitions (M&A). They construct an investment model of FDI using subsidiary’s investment (F Dl financed by retained earnings). So, he argues that it is worthwhile to investigate empirically the effect of both the home country’s rate of taxation and its system of taxing foreign-source income. 11 particular M&A tax-code provisions. The model is neoclassical in character, and is based on the assumptions of the neoclassical model. Their simulation results. which are based on their investment model of FDI, suggest that the Tax Refomr Act of 1986 (TRA86) decreased the incentives for worldwide firms to invest in all assets other than equipment, and that TRA86 decreased the overall investment incentives of territorial firms. However, in reality, this prediction was not supported by the actual FDI trend. They conclude that the FDI boom in the late 19803 might not have been significantly affected by TRA86. Swenson (1994) analyzes F D1 in 18 industries, for the years 1979 through 1991. She uses average tax rates calculated by Tax Analysts. She finds that the response of worldwide investors to the US average tax rate was positive and statistically significant. For territorial investors, the effect of the average tax rate on FDI is much smaller and statistically insignificant. These results are consistent with the argument of Scholes and Wolfson (1992) that FDI by worldwide firms responds positively to the tax rate, and this makes total FDI respond positively to the tax rate. I replicate her estimation, and the results will be discussed in chapter 3. Table 1 shows the differences in F DI data, the tax rate measures used, and the main results, among the empirical studies above. 12 Table 1. Summary of Empirical Studies Hartman Boskin & Young Slemrod Swenson (1984) Gale (1987) (1988) (1990) (1994) FDI data capital flow capitalflow capital flow capital flow acquisition and establishment (1965-1979) (1956-1984) (1953-1984) (1960-1987) (1979-1991) Main A fter-tax After-tax A fter-tar ME TR AE T R Explanarory Rate of return Rate of return Rate of return Variable Conclusion (US. tax negative negative negative negative positive Effect on F DI) "' AETR stands for the average effective corporate tax rate, and METR for the marginal effective corporate tax rate 13 2. Data Issues 2.1. FDI Data There are two different kinds of FDI data available: one is the acquisition and establishment data, and the other is the direct investment capital flows data (balance-of- payments data). Both data sets are available in the Survey of Current Business published by the Bureau of Economic Analysis. The acquisition and establishment data set consists of the actual outlays of foreign investors to establish or acquire new US affiliates. Roughly speaking, establishment involves creation of a new legal entity by a foreigner, and acquisition involves obtaining a voting interest in an existing US. business by a foreigner. These data are available since 1979. Swenson (1994) uses this data set. The capital flow data consist of equity capital, intercompany debt between US affiliates and its parents, and reinvested earnings. If a foreign affiliate borrows in the US in order to buy a machine, this transaction will not appear in this data. Hartman (I984), Boskin & Gale (1987), Young (1988), and Slemrod (1990) use this data set. The acquisition and establishment data and the capital flow data provide different measures of the annual growth in FDI in the US. The acquisition and establishment data cover the actual outlays to establish or acquire new US. affiliates, regardless of how or by whom the investment was financed. Thus the outlays may be made by either the foreign parent or an existing U.S. affiliate, and the source of financing may be other than the foreign parent group, such as local borrowing by existing U.S. affiliates. In contrast, the balance-of-payments data cover only transactions between foreign parent groups and US. affiliates. If, for example, a US. affiliate of a German chemical manufacturer I4 acquired a US chemical company by borrowing funds in the US, the borrowed funds would be included in the acquisition and establishment data but not in the capital flow data, because the acquisition did not involve funds from the foreign parent”. As mentioned above, the capital flow data cannot capture the foreign direct investment financed by borrowing in the US. Young (1988) admits the limitation of the capital flow data by saying “F D1 in this study is most accurately thought of as a financial transaction. It does not necessarily mean purchase of real assets, such as plants and equipment, and does not include funds borrowed in the US” Auerbach and Hassett (1993) point out that the capital flow data are not directly related to physical investment, which is of interest to the researcher, and on which are based the theoretical models to form effective tax rates. Swenson (1994) also agrees that the acquisition and establishment data provide a more accurate assessment of the tax effect on FDI. So, I think the acquisition and establishment data set is more appropriate than the capital flow data for explaining investment behavior. The acquisition F DI, the establishment FDI, and the total FDI (sum of acquisition F DI and establishment FDI) can be broken down by industries. And the total FDI can be disaggregated by some major foreign investor countries. In chapter 4, I disaggregate total F DI (the sum of the acquisition FDI and the establishment FDI) by four industriesl3 . And in chapter 5, I use the total FDI by seven '2 Quijano (1990). '3 I calculate the average effective tax rates on the basis of corporate income tax return data in Statistics of Income (SOI) Bulletin published by the lntemal Revenue Service. So, my industry classification is restricted by the industry classification of the SOI Bulletin (eight industries: Agriculture-Forestry-Fishing, Mining, Construction, Manufacturing, Transportation and Public Utilities, Wholesale and Retail Trade, Finance-lnsurance-Real Estate, and Services). And FDI data in Survey of Current Business have some data suppressions to avoid disclosure of data of individual companies. Therefore, to avoid losing too much information, I consolidate some industries into one industry. The four industries are (1) manufacturing, (2) 15 major investor countries. In chapter 6, I disaggregate the acquisition FDI and the establishment FDI by four industries. According to these data sets. most FDI are accounted for by the acquisition FDI (see Figure 2). trade, (3) services and FIRE (finance, insurance, and real estate), and (4) other industries. 16 Figure 2. Foreign Direct Investment in the US. 1979 — 1996 90000 FDI in the US. in millions of US. dollars LL «Sta? +acq i—N—est ”w l 17 2.2. Data on Effective Tax Rates Since the tax burden of a corporation is dependent on many factors, such as corporate financial policy, inflation expectations, uncertainty, and the tax code, it is difficult to measure the exact burden of corporate income taxation. Especially, the tax code has lots of complexities, such as various deductions, credits, and exemptions, which make the statutory tax rate different from actual tax burden. The average effective tax rate and the marginal effective tax rate are contrived to estimate the actual tax burden or to measure the incentive effects of taxation. The average effective tax rate is said to be a good measure of the tax burden of existing firms, but it is not necessarily a good measure of the impact of taxes on the incentives to make new investment. In contrast, the marginal effective tax rate measures the estimate of the net tax burden on the expected income from a marginal investment. So it is said to be a good measure of the incentive effect of taxes on new investment, but it cannot be a good measure of the tax burden of existing businesses”. Swenson ( l 994) uses the average effective corporate tax rates as the main explanatory variable for FDI in the US. However, Slemrod (1990) argues that the marginal effective corporate tax rate is a better measure of expected tax burden on a prospective new investment, and uses the marginal effective corporate tax rate as the tax- rate measure. All studies dealing with the effects of taxes on F DI use corporate level effective tax rates rather than the total of corporate and personal level effective tax rates. '4 Fullerton (1984), p. 23. 18 This is because foreign investors pay taxes at the corporate level, but not at the personal level. In order to see which tax rate measure is the more appropriate explanatory variable for F DI behavior, I use both average effective corporate tax rates and marginal effective corporate tax rates. The average effective corporate tax rate is generally defined by actual corporate taxes paid as a proportion of corporate income.15 The average effective tax rate is used to measure the overall tax burden of existing firms. Tax Foundation’s calculation of US average effective corporate tax rates is one of the most recent calculations of the AETR”. Tax Foundation calculates the annual U.S. AETR for the years 1945 — 1998. I follow the method of Tax Foundation in calculating the average effective tax rates. I calculate the average effective corporate tax rate, based on Statistics of Income Bulletin (801 Bulletin) data published by the lntemal Revenue Service (IRS). The average effective tax rate is calculated by taking federal corporate income tax paid divided by net income. Figure 3 shows my calculation of the AETR for the US. as a whole. Table 7 in chapter 4 presents my calculation of the average effective tax rates by industry. The calculation of the AETR of Tax Analysts and that of Tax Foundation are compared in Figure 5 in Chapter 3. The marginal effective tax rate measures the fraction of the real pretax rate of return to a new investment that will be collected as taxes. It is used to measure the incentive effect of taxes on new investment. One of the most recent calculations of the marginal effective tax rates is the one by Gravelle (1994). She calculates the US overall METR for the years 1953 - 1989. Figure 4 compares my calculation of the METR and '5 Fullerton (1984), p. 24. '6 Moody (1998). 19 that of Gravelle (1994). The major difference between my own calculation and Gravelle’s calculation of the METR is the expected inflation data. While Gravelle (1994) uses the expected inflation rates of the Drexel-Burnham-Lambert Decision Makers Poll, I use the expected inflation rates of the Livingston Survey data maintained by the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. The methodology and data used in calculating the METR are presented in an appendix. 20 Figure 3. The Average Effective Corporate Tax Rates in the US. 40% i 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 0% Source 5%g The Average Effective Corporate Tax Rates 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1988 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1998 : My own calculation, based on corporate tax return data in Statistics of Income Bulletin published by the lntemal Revenue Service. 21 i I 4' Figure 4. Comparison of the Marginal Effective Corporate Tax Rates 70% 50% 40% -' 30% 20% f 10% i 0% The marginal effective corporate tax rates 60% - 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 Sources: Gravelle (1994) and text. 22 l-O—KIM .. ‘ 1+.-___._§:av_¢"_¢x One of the most important differences between this paper and the paper of Swenson (1994) is the calculation of the average effective tax rates. She uses the average effective tax rates calculated by Tax Analysts. but I calculate the AETR using the corporate tax return data from the Internal Revenue Service (IRS). Tax Analysts use data for the 500 largest companies in calculating the AETR for the years 1980 — 1984, and for the 1,000 largest companies for the years 1985 — 1989. The data are derived from the Form IO-Ks that publicly held corporations are required to file with the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). More detailed discussion of the Tax Analysts’ calculation of the AETR will be found in chapter 3. My calculation of the AETR depends on the data on corporation income tax returns in SO] Bulletin. The data are broken down by eight broad industries. The data contain the income tax returns filed by all US. corporations, so the number of firms included in the IRS data is several million. In 1980, the number of returns filed was 3.7 million. and in 1996 it was 4.6 million. 23 CHAPTER III THE NEW VIEW OF TAXES AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT l. The New View According to Scholes and Wolfson (1992). if two assets give rise to the same pre- tax cash flows, but the cash flows to one asset are taxed more favorably than those to the other asset, taxpayers will bid for the tax-favored asset. This competition for the tax- favored assets causes the relative price of the tax-advantaged assets to rise. This competition continues until the equality of the post-tax rate of return between the tax- advantaged and tax-disadvantaged assets is restored. As a result, the price of the tax- favored asset will increase, and the before-tax rate of return on the tax-favored asset will decrease. Scholes and Wolfson refer to this reduction in the before-tax rate of return of the lightly taxed asset as an ‘implicit tax’. They use an example of municipal bonds, which are issued by state and local governments. The interest earned on municipal bonds is exempted from federal income taxation. Investors bid up the price of these municipal bonds, such that their before-tax rate of return is lower than the return on fully taxed bonds Scholes and Wolfson extend the ‘implicit tax’ hypothesis to the discussion of the effects of taxes on FDI. They suggest that investors whose home country use a worldwide tax system can respond positively to a change in the host country’s tax rate. They state this as follows: 24 “One might be tempted to suppose that if tax rates are lower in a foreign country than they are domestically, it follows that after-tax rates of return on marginal investments should be higher in the foreign country. But this ignores the very real possibility that pretax rates of return in the foreign country may be lower than that available domestically. In countries where the tax rate on income is relatively low, one would expect competition to force down pretax profitability. In other words, the foreign investments will bear implicit taxes. --------- Implicit taxes can arise because the foreign country encourages investment by offering generous tax benefits, and competition for the right to garner these benefits results in lower before-tax rates of return. --------- (for worldwide investors) it is only necessary to compare before-tax rates of return for one-year horizon investment.”l7 Swenson (1994) makes Scholes and Wolfson’s argument in a more general form, which predicts the response of investors from territorial countries as well as that of investors from worldwide countries to a change in the US. tax rate. She also provides empirical evidence supporting Scholes and Wolfson’s ‘implicit tax’ hypothesis in the context of F DI and taxes. According to the argument of Swenson (1994), firms invest until their after-tax rate of return on the investment is equal to the return on the passive asset. In her own notation, Rus(1-Tus) = RF, where RF is the after-tax rate of return on an alternative passive asset (or requisite return). In this view, an increase in the US. tax rate (T as) increases the before-tax return on US. assets (Rug). Since foreign investors from countries with a territorial tax system do not pay taxes to their home country, they receive the full U.S. after-tax return (RT = RUSH-Tits] = RF). Firms from countries with a worldwide tax system pay taxes to their home country and get a foreign tax credit, so they ultimately earn RW = RUSH-Tug) + RUSTUS — RUSTH = RUSH-TH). According to '7 Scholes and Wolfson (1992), pp. 253-254. 25 Swenson (1994), firms from countries with a territorial tax system are not greatly affected by an increase in Tu; because their after-tax return on direct investment in the US. (R r = RU5[1 -TU5]) is fixed at RF regardless of the US. corporate tax rate. But, firms from worldwide tax countries increase their investment in response to an increase in Tug, because an increase in the US. tax rate (Tug) leads to an increase in the US. pretax rate of return (Rug). These changes do not affect the investment incentive of territorial firms, but they do make worldwide firms increase their investment in the US. Accordingly, FDI in the US should respond positively to the US. tax rate. 2. Problems of the New View The conclusion of the new view is derived from two assumptions: perfect capital mobility among countries, and perfect mobility between physical and financial assets. Under the assumption of perfect international capital mobility, an immediate adjustment in the pretax rate of return is possible. If the assumption of perfect capital mobility does not hold, the conclusion that worldwide investors should respond positively to an increase in the US. tax rate cannot be derived. However, what is generally observed and accepted in the related literature is far remote from these assumptions. Under the assumption of perfect capital mobility between physical and financial assets, the conclusion that territorial investors should not respond to a change in the US. tax rate is possible. And this assumption is also far from reality. Therefore, the “asset competition” view can be said to have limitations in explaining the real behavior of direct investment, because of its unrealistic assumptions. This section discusses the assumption of the new 26 view in more detail. Capital mobility between countries The asset competition view (the New View) can hold only under the situation of perfect competition and perfect capital mobility between countries. Scholes and Wolfson (1992, p. 84) state, “. . .we assume that markets are perfect. In this setting, no transaction costs are incurred to undertake investments or to manage them. All investors are assumed to possess identical information regarding the future cash flows from investment alternatives. Moreover, investors act as though their behavior has no influence on the prices at which assets can be bought and sold.” Swenson (1994, p. 249) states, “. . .we begin with the premise that asset competition, and perfect capital mobility drive the after- tax rate of return on US. assets into line with the world rate of return.” However, the consensus in the academic literature is that capital is not perfectly mobile among countries. Feldstein and Horioka (1980) and Mishkin (1984) report empirical evidence suggesting that capital is internationally quite immobile. Feldstein and Horioka analyze the relation between savings rates and investment rates of the 21 OECD countries for the period 1960 — 1974. Their basic finding is that the correlation between savings rates and investment rates is close to one (0.89). They conclude that this result is not consistent with perfect capital mobility. Mishkin analyzes real interest-rate differentials among seven developed counties for the period 1967 -— 1979. He finds that there exist real interest-rate differentials across countries. Persistent differentials in real interest rates are also inconsistent with perfect capital mobility. More recently, F eldstein and Bacchetta (1990) find that, while there is still a 27 positive correlation between savings rates and investment rates, the size of the correlation has decreased during the 19805. This appears to be have been due to (1) the relaxation of explicit capital controls in some countries, (2) the ongoing integration of the world capital market, and (3) the vast increase in the borrowing needs of the United States. Nevertheless, the results of Feldstein and Bacchetta are still consistent with a substantial degree of international capital immobility. They find that, even in the 19805, each additional dollar of domestic saving is associated with more than 50 cents of additional investment in the domestic economy. Frankel (1990) and Obstfeld (1993) provide reviews of the capital-immobility literature. Obstfeld concludes that “Capital mobility appears noticeably lower between industrial economies than it is within them, although intereconomy capital mobility certainly has increased over time. . . .. It is doubtful that capital will ever be as mobile between nations as it can be within them. The mere existence of national governments sovereign within their borders means that no investor can think about domestic and foreign assets in quite the same way.””3 Gordon and Bovenberg (1996) provide six possible explanations for the observed capital immobility: Existence of capital controls, high transaction costs, exchange-rate risk, fear of expropriation, asymmetric information across countries, and market power of large countries. And they argue that the most plausible explanation is asymmetric information between foreigners and domestic residents. They state this as follows: “Investors, by living and working in a particular country, know much more about the economic prospects of that country than they do about those in other countries. When foreigners try to acquire a firm in the country, they can easily end up being overcharged by domestic owners, who have access to better information not only '8 Obstfeld (1993), pp. 66-67. 28 about that specific firm, but also about future government policies affecting the firm. When foreigners buy domestic inputs or services or pay domestic income taxes, their lack of information can again lead to overpayment. Foreigners’ lack of knowledge can result also in a less efficient use of resources, due for example to their poorer ability to forecast market demand in a new setting or to deal with idiosyncratic aspects of the domestic contract law, the local distribution system and supply network, and local customs governing labor relations.”'9 Substitutability between direct investment and portfolio investment The perfect-capital-mobility assumption of the asset competition view is a result of not distinguishing direct investment and portfolio investment. That is, the asset competition view regards direct investment as a perfect substitute for portfolio investment. However, the immediate or quick bid up for the tax-favored asset is possible only in the case of portfolio investment. It is generally accepted that portfolio investment is not a perfect substitute for FDI. Caves (1996) and Graham and Krugman (1995) list several reasons why direct investment is different from portfolio investment. First of all, the motivation of direct investment is different from that of portfolio investment. The primary motivation of FDI is to extend control over foreign businesses, because this extension of control can improve corporate strategic value in a variety of ways. The primary motivation of portfolio investment is simply to earn higher returns. In other words, portfolio investment pursues higher Short-term returns, while direct investment is carried out pursuing long-terrn returns, including intangible benefits. Secondly, as Auerbach and Hassett (1993) point out, a significant portion of FDI is financed locally. If the motivation of FDI were simply the higher interest rate, FDI should not be financed '9 Gordon and Bovenberg (1996), p. 1059. 29 locally. Thirdly, FDI among advanced countries typically moves in both directions across national boundaries. If FDI were merely designed to find a higher rate of return, then F DI should move unilaterally from a country with a lower rate of return to other countries with higher rates of return. Finally, shifting capital between direct investment and portfolio investment entails adjustment costs and time. Therefore, portfolio investment cannot be a perfect substitute for direct investment. Capital mobility between physical assets and financial assets Swenson (1994) assumes that the after-tax rate of return on physical assets and financial assets is always equal. In her own expression, the equality of Rugfl-Tus) = RF always holds. But, this equation can only be satisfied under the equilibrium state after every adjustment process finishes, or under perfect mobility between physical assets and financial assets. In reality, the economy is not in an equilibrium state, even though it is always moving toward an equilibrium state. And as physical investment is not a perfect substitute for portfolio investment, capital is not so mobile between physical assets and financial assets. 3. Problems in the New View’s Empirical Analysis Even though the conclusion of the New View depends heavily on unrealistic assumptions, Swenson (1994) provides some estimation results supporting the argument of the New View. She gets a positive and significant FDI elasticity with respect to the 30 AETR. So, I try to replicate her estimation. By using a data set that is very similar to hers”, I find a positive FDI elasticity with respect to the average effective corporate tax rate. However, the elasticity is much smaller than hers, and it is statistically insignificant. In addition, I find that there are some serious mistakes in her analysis that may make her results unreliable. One problem is that the average effective tax rate calculated by Tax Analysts is not an accurate estimate of the US. average effective corporate tax rate. That is, Tax Analysts’ calculation of the average effective tax rate has some bias, and so it does not seem that Tax Analysts’ average effective tax rate is a representative US. average tax rate. The other problem is that Swenson uses Tax Analysts’ data very arbitrarily in her analysis. These points will be explained in depth below. 3.1. Problems of the Average Effective Tax Rates by Tax Analysts Tax Analysts’ main goal of their calculation of the AETR seems to be to calculate large US. firms’ overall average effective tax rates. According to the methodology part of the book Effective Corporate Tax Rates, Tax Analysts selected 500 or 1,000 of the largest US firms, ranked in terms of gross sales and assets, as their sample firms, and calculated overall US. average effective corporate tax rates for the years 1980 - 1989. In turn, Tax Analysts grouped these firms into from 54 to 91 industrieszl, and calculated the average effective corporate tax rates for each industry. 2° Swenson’s sample period is 1979-1991, and she says her data source is Eflective Corporate Tax Rates by Tax Analysts (Swenson, 1994, pp. 254-255). But, I cannot get Tax Analysts’ average effective tax rate data for the years of 1979, 1990, and 1991. According to Tax Analysts, they published six volumes of the book Eflective Corporate Tax Rates and the books have the AETR data only for the years 1980-1989. 2' 54 industries for the years 1980 — 1984, 91 industries in 1985, 84 industries in 1986, 83 industries in 31 The first problem of using Tax Analysts’ AETR in FDI analysis lies in the fact that Tax Analysts’ data are based on information in the financial statements of only the largest US. firms. Firms have a tendency to make their financial statements look good for a variety of reasons. And there is some evidence22 that large firms engage in more deception. Therefore, it is difficult to say that the average effective tax rates calculated by using Tax Analysts’ data are the representative average effective tax rates of the United States. Accordingly. the result from the estimation with biased data cannot be a reliable one. Figure 5 compares Tax Analysts" average effective corporate tax rates with Tax Foundation’s average effective corporate tax rates”. It turns out that TA’S average effective tax rates are substantially different from the average effective corporate tax rates calculated using more information. The second problem of Tax Analysts’ estimates for the average effective tax rates is associated with the calculation of the average effective tax rates by industry. Tax Analysts’ selected 500 or 1,000 largest US. firms and categorized them into 54 - 91 industries, according to the Standard Industrial Classification. This method may result in more biased estimates for the industry-level average effective tax rates, because some industries may include very few firms. If Tax Analysts’ purpose of calculating AETR were a calculation of large firms’ AETR for the selected industry, a more appropriate sampling method would be to select firms ranked in the top 20 or 30 percent in each industry. 1987 and 1988, and 74 industries in 1989. 22 US. Department of Treasury (1999) and Manzon and Plesko (2001). 23 Tax Foundation (1998) calculated the US. average effective tax rates by using Statistics of Income data (by IRS) for the years 1950-1994. 32 Figure 5. Comparison of the AETR of Tax Analysts and that of Tax Foundation ‘ Average Effective Corporate Tax Rates l 35% i l 30% 25% - 20% l 7 g _ - '—0— Tax Analysts -If Tax Foundation , 150A, ,_____g__#_____,________ _-‘ WW 7,. W L!_ .__,,_,A . - .__ . .. .,_i, _-M,_ 1 100A, __.__ _______,_L__,_,_#___‘, ,,,, ._,__,__-_, , . ________ii _ - __ i ‘ 5%._____.i,, , , .,,,_,________,, _- ifi-__ , .. ”UL—H _ n j 0% - - . l 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 ‘ YEAR 33 3.2. Problems of the Way the New View uses Tax Analysts’ Data Since the industry classification of Swenson (1994) is different from that of Tax Analysts, Swenson recalculates the average effective tax rates in the US. by using Tax Analysts’ data. The only information about how Swenson estimates the average effective tax rates by using Tax Analysts’ data is Table 3 in Swenson (1994), which compares the two-year average of the effective tax rate before the Tax Reform Act 1986 (TRA 1986, hereafter) and after TRA 1986. In order to find out how she uses Tax Analysts’ data and check out whether my replication of her estimates for the AETR is correct, I try to reproduce her Table 3. Table 2 compares the numbers in Swenson’s Table 3 and the replication results of my own. I can reproduce her Table 3 except for the ‘petroleum industry’, ‘finance industry’, and ‘insurance industry’. That is, the results of reproduction are close for all industries except these three industries. She might have made errors in calculating the average effective corporate tax rates of these three industries. Table 2 simply indicates that I understand how Swenson estimates the average effective tax rates by using Tax Analysts’ data. By reproducing Swenson’s Table 3, I find that she uses the AETR of a large-digit industry to represent that of a small-digit industry. That is, she uses the AETR of a subset of an industry to represent the AETR of the entire industry. In the case of the year 1988, the number of industries used in Swenson’s analysis is 18, but that of Tax Analysts is 83. To calculate the AETR for each of the 18 industries, Swenson should have regrouped Tax Analysts’ 83 industries into 18 industries, and then should have calculated the AETR for the small-digit industries using all of the information from the large-digit industries that are included in that small-digit industry. To make this point clearly, and to Show how this 34 method distorts the AETR for each of the 18 industries, Table 3 is presented. Taking a look at the ‘food industry’ of Swenson’s classification in Table 3, the ‘food & kindred products’ industry, ‘miscellaneous food production’ industry, ‘dairy products’ industry, ‘meat products’ industry, and ‘beverages‘ industry of Tax Analysts’ classification are included in the ‘food industry’. The average tax rate of the entire food industry is 30.32%, but that of food & kindred products is 33.46%. That is, Swenson uses the AETR of the ‘food & kindred’ industry to represent that of the entire ‘food’ industry. The situation of other industries is the same as that of the ‘food industry.’ 35 Table 2. Replication Result of Swenson (1994)’s Table 3 Table 3 in Swenson (1994) Replication Results INDUSTRY (84+85).’2 (87+88)l2 (84+85)i2 (87+88)/2 Mining 29.2 17.3 29.2 17 3 Petroleum 45.9 35.9 16.3 26.0 Food 27.3 32.8 27.3 32.8 Chemicals 21.2 28.2 21.2 28.2 Metals 30.9 32.5 28.0 32.5 Machinery (Non-electrical) 24.6 26.0 24.0 26.0 Machinery (Electrical) 28.0 30.0 27.4 30.0 Printing & Publishing 34.3 38.2 34.3 38.2 Rubber & Plastics 18.7 22.3 18.7 22.3 Stone, Clay, and Glass 27.3 30.6 27.3 30.6 Instruments 22.7 24.9 22.7 24.9 Wholesale trade 26.0 . 33.2 26.1 33.2 Retail trade 33.5 37.1 33.5 37.1 Banking 9.9 18.1 9.9 18.0 Finance 16.0 19.4 17.7 16.2 Insurance 15.9 19.4 4.3 19.4 Real estate 21.2 24.1 21.2 24.1 Services 30.4 31.4 30.4 31.4 36 Table 3. Illustration of Swenson’s Calculation of the AETR for Each Industry Swenson's 18 industries Tax AIILIV'SIS. 83 industries (in 1988) AETR Mining Mining(l3) 0.1078 Oil and gas extraction (8) 0 469 Total (21) O 1299 Petroleum Petroleum refining (26) 02702 Food Food & kindred products (7) 0.3346 Food production lvliscellaneous (19) 0.2833 Dairy products (4) 0,3806 Meat products (10) 0.2877 Beverages (7) 0.2801 Total (47) 0.3032 Chemicals Chemicals (20) 0.29 Chemicals; Miscellaneous (21) 0.2499 Drugs (17) 0.2634 Soap and other detergents (12) 0.2555 Total (70) 0 2715 Metals Metals: Fabricated (24) 0.3183 Metals: Primary (25) O 2226 Total (49) 0.2394 Non-electric Machinery and equipment: General industrial (12) 0.234 Machinery Machinery. Construction, mining, and materials handling (10) 0.2774 Machinery: Special industrial (3) 0.3656 Machinery and equipment. Metal working (3) 0.2464 Engines and turbines (7) 02569 Total (35) 0.2669 Electric Electrical computing and office machines (22) 0.1047 Machinery Electrical: Household appliances (2) 0.2716 Electrical components and accessories (15) 0.3828 Electrical and electronic machinery equipment. and supplies (8) 0.2579 Electrical machinery, equipment. and supplies: Miscellaneous. (9) 0.1349 Equipment-communication (19) 04235 Total (75) 0.2366 Printing & Printing“ Commercial (9) 0.3486 Publishing Publishing and printing-newspapers (13) 0.326 Publishing and printing-periodicals and books (8) 0.4023 Total (30) 0.3437 Rubber & Rubber (5) 0.2259 Plastics Plastics (6) 0.256 Total (11) 0,2445 37 Table 3 (Cont’d). Swenson's 18 industries Tax Analysts” 83 industries (in 1988) AETR Stone, clay, Stone. clay. glass. and concrete products ( l3) 0 3416 and glass Instruments Measuring and controlling instruments (26) 0201 Wholesale trade Durable goods (23) 0.3076 Nondurable goods: Drugs (4) 0.3754 Nondurable goods: Miscellaneous (20) 0.3201 Total (47) 03202 Retail trade Apparel and accessory stores ( l 1) 0.3171 Building materials and hardware stores (5) 0 2808 Department stores (9) 0.3138 Drug stores (6) 0.4243 Eating and drinking places (12) 0 3362 Grocery stores (19) 0.2671 Miscellaneous (14) 0.3734 Variety stores (13) 03148 Total (89) 0.3024 Banking Banking: National banks (50) 0.16081 Banking: State banks (40) 0.1889 Total (90) 0.1704 Finance Federal savings and loan (4) 0.4379 Credit agencies: Other than banks (1 1) 0.2791 Savings and loan holding companies (17) 0.2731 Financial services (6) 02227 Total (38) 02607 Insurance Insurance (36) 02471 Real Estate Real estate (7) 0.2316 Servrces Services: Advertising agencies (3) 04133 Services: Enginering and architectural (5) 0 3196 Services: Personal (4) 03198 Services: Computer and data processing (5) 0.1057 Services: Health services (10) 0.305 Services: Hotels and motels (2) 0.2589 Services: Miscellaneous (12) 0.3226 Services: Motion pictures (3) 0 31 12 Total (44) 0.2671 Foot notes) 1. Numbers in parentheses: number of sample firms. 2. Tax Analysts’ industry in bold font: Swenson has this industry represent the entire industry. 38 3.3. Replication Results of Swenson’s Estimation Industry-level argrlysis Table 4 compares my replication results of Swenson’s industry-level estimation and Swenson’s original estimation results. The first two columns present a part of the original estimation results of Swenson (1994, Table 4). These columns Show that the magnitudes of the elasticities of the AETR are positive (around one: 0.75 - 1.13), and the elasticities are statistically significant. Because column two is Swenson’s baseline specification, I reestimate a second column with data for the period of 1980 —198924. Column three and column four report the replication result. The coefficients in column three are GLS estimates, and those in column four are OLS estimates with heteroskedasticity-robust t-value. In both columns. the estimated elasticities of F DI with respect to the AETR are positive, but they are very small and statistically insignificant. Since F D1 in the US. might be affected by the US business situation, U.S. real GDP might be thought to be a relevant control variable. And if US. real GDP is correlated 2’ The number of observations in Table 4 of Swenson (1994) is 229. Considering Swenson’s industry classification (18 industries) and the period of analysis (13 years: 1979-1991), there must be 5 missing observations in her data set. However, I find that there are more than 5 missing observations. In early volumes of the Survey of Current Business (SCB for 1979, 1980, 1981, and 1982), there are only 13 industries that match with Swenson’s 18 industries. And there are also some missing observations arising from data suppressions in the Survey of Current Business for the purpose of avoiding disclosure of data of individual companies. In addition to missing observations in the FDI data, there are also some missing observations in the AETR data. The AETRs calculated using Tax Analysts’ data indicate that the Banking industry and the Insurance industry have negative tax rates for several years (early 19805). Taking logarithm of the negative AETRs results in missing observations. 39 with one ofthe explanatory variables, omitting real U.S. GDP will cause biased estimates. Therefore, as Hartman (1984). Boskin and Gale (1987). and Young (1988) do. I try to add U.S. real GDP as a control variable. The fifth column shows the results of the estimation with US. real GDP. U.S. real GDP appears to have a strong explanatory power, and the F DI-elasticity with respect to the AETR becomes close to zero, and the statistical significance of the estimates is reduced greatly. As mentioned in the previous section, Swenson uses the AETR of a large-digit industry to represent that of a small-digit industry. Common sense tells us to calculate the AETRs for each industry by using all data of the sample firms in each industry. Therefore, I correct the industry-level AETRS by dividing the US. taxes paid by firms in each industry by the net income of the firms in each industry. To see if the use of the corrected AETRs for each industry leads to the same result, I redo the estimation with the corrected AETRS. Column six and column seven show the reestimation results with these corrected AETRs. The F DI-elasticities with respect to the AETR are much smaller (almost zero) than those in columns three and four. The estimation results using the AETRS for each industry calculated more appropriately no longer support Swenson’s conclusion. Column eight shows the results of the estimation with US. real GDP. Real U.S. GDP appears to have a strong explanatory power, and the AETR variable turns out to have no explanatory power. In conclusion, Swenson’s estimation suffers from the mismatching problem that the AETRs of the large-digit industry represent the small-digit industry. And her estimation results also might have the ‘omitted variable bias.’ I conclude that I cannot replicate Swenson’s industry-level estimation with data the set available, and that it is hard to think of Swenson’s estimation result as reliable. 40 Table 4. Replication result of Swenson’s industry-level estimation Swenson Replicated Corrected (1994, Table 4) GLS GLS GLS OLS OLS GLS OLS OLS log(AETR) 1.13 0.75 0.23 0.24 0.14 -0.02 0.06 -0.03 (3.26) (2.30) (0.93) [0.93] [0.56] (-0.13) [0.23] {-0.13} log(EX) -l.38 -l.42 -1.82 -1.79 -1.28 -l.96 -l.95 -l.38 (-2.38) (-3.01) (-5. l 3) [-4.22] {-2.83] (-5.50) [~5.15] {-3.19] Time trend 0.08 0.08 0.16 0.15 -0.35 0.17 0.16 -0.38 (3.94) (4.69) (8.06) [4.75] {-2.96] (8.33) [5.08] {-3.17] Industry no yes yes yes yes yes yes yes dummies log(GDP) - - - - 15.64 - - 16.38 [4.36] [4.73] N 229 229 151 151 151 153 153 153 R-squared 0.16 0.45 - 0.55 0.59 - 0.55 0.60 * AETR and EX stand for the average effective tax rate and exchange rate, respectively. " Number in ( ) is ordinary t-value and number in [ ] is heteroskedasticity-robust t-value. 41 Country-level analysis Table 5 shows the replication result of Swenson’s country-level analysis. The first column is a part of Swenson’s (1994) Table 6, which is her baseline specification. The first column of Table 5 shows that, while the estimated F DI-elasticity with respect to the AETR for investors from worldwide countries is positive (2.99) and statistically significant, the elasticity for investors from territorial countries is close to zero (0.09) and statistically insignificant. The second column shows my replicated estimation results, which seem to support Swenson’s results that worldwide investors respond positively to the US. effective corporate tax rate. but territorial investors do not respond to US. effective corporate tax rate. However, it is hard to say that Swenson’s estimation is reliable, even though Swenson’s country-level estimation is qualitatively replicated. Since F D1 in the US. might be affected by the US. business situation, U.S. real GDP might be thought to be a relevant control variable. And if US. real GDP is correlated with one of the explanatory variables, omitting U.S. real GDP will cause biased estimates. Therefore, I try to add U.S. real GDP as a control variable. The third column shows the results of the estimation with US. real GDP. Adding log(GDP) reduces the magnitudes of the FDI elasticities with respect to the AETR for both worldwide and territorial investors. The estimated FDI elasticity with respect to the AETR for worldwide investors is much smaller than before, and is now statistically insignificant. And the estimated FDI elasticity for territorial investors becomes negative, and is still statistically insignificant. On the other hand, U.S. real GDP itself appears to have a strong explanatory power. 42 In addition, as mentioned earlier, Swenson uses Tax Analysts‘ data in calculating the average effective tax rate. Tax Analysts’ data are based on information in the financial statements of only the largest US firms. Since there is some evidence that large firms engage in more deception, it is difficult to say that the average effective tax rates calculated by using Tax Analysts’ data are the representative average effective tax rate of the United States. Accordingly, the results from the estimation with biased data cannot be considered to be reliable. 4. Summary Theoretically, the prediction of the new view is based on two highly unrealistic assumptions: perfect capital mobility among countries, and perfect mobility between physical and financial assets. If these assumptions do not hold, it is not possible to derive the predictions that worldwide investors should respond positively to an increase in the US. tax rate, and that territorial investors should not respond to a change in the US. tax rate. Instead, what is generally observed and accepted in the related literature is far remote from these assumptions. . And empirically, there are some serious problems in the estimation process of the new view. The estimates for the average effective tax rates are not so reliable. An important control variable is missing. And the estimation results of the new view cannot be replicated. In the following chapters, I analyze some issues regarding the relationship between FDI in the US. and the US. effective corporate tax rate, with more appropriate estimates for the average effective tax rate and more appropriate econometric models. 43 Table 5. Replication result of Swenson’s country-level analysis Swenson (1994, Table 6) log(WWTAX) 2.99 3.83 1.56 (2.66) (2.57) (0.87) log(TTAX) 0.09 1.16 -1 .11 (0.09) (1.05) (-0.73) log(EX) -0.39 -l .75 -l .71 (-1.42) (-2.70) (-2.73) Time trend yes yes yes Country dummies yes yes yes log(GDP) - - 19.41 (2.12) N 69 57 57 R-squared 0.36 0.66 0.69 * WWTAX, TTAX, and EX stand for the average effective tax rate for worldwide worldwide investors, that for territorial investors, and exchange rate, respectively. ** Number in ( ) is t-statistics. 44 CHAPTER IV OVERALL U.S. TAX EFFECT ON F D1 1. Tax Consequences of the U.S. Source Income of Foreign Investors According to the definition of foreign direct investment in Chapter 1, a foreign person’s establishment of an unincorporated branch (same legal entity as the parent firm) and investment in a U.S. corporation (separate legal entity) are both considered FDI in the United States. The U.S. tax treatment of dividends and branch income is determined by the U.S. source of income rule (lntemal Revenue Code, section 861 - section 865) and the bilateral income-tax treaty between the U.S. and the foreign investor’s home country. According to the U.S. source of income rule, the source of dividend income is determined by the residence of the corporation paying the dividends. And the residence is determined by the corporation’s country of incorporation. Therefore, a U.S. corporation owned by foreign persons is subject to U.S. corporate income tax on its net income, and in addition, the dividend income of the U.S. corporation is subject to flat 30% withholding tax when dividends are repatriated. Usually, the withholding tax rate is reduced to 0% - 15% by income tax treaties. For example, without treaty provisions, the U.S. dividend income of a Canadian firm is subject to 30% withholding tax, but the U.S.- Canada Income Tax Treaty reduces this rate to 5%25 . 2’ Protocol Amending the Convention Between the United States of America and Canada With Respect to Taxes on Income and on Capital, Article 5. 45 Business profits of a U.S. branch are considered effectively connected income26. Therefore, they are subject to U.S. corporate income tax, but not subject to withholding tax. To equalize the tax treatment of foreign corporations operating through a U.S. branch and those operating through a U.S. subsidiary, TRA 1986 introduced a new branch profits tax, which imposes a 30% tax on the repatriated profits of a U.S. branch of a foreign corporation”. Therefore, the tax burden on the U.S. income of a foreign investor depends on the rates of U.S. corporate income tax and withholding tax (or branch profits tax). However, for simplicity, I ignore withholding taxes, as the previous studies do”. 2. Empirical Model Specification In this section, I introduce an econometric model that is designed to explain overall FDI in the United States. Thus, at this stage, all F D1 are considered together, regardless of whether the FDI is in the form of an acquisition or an establishment, and regardless of whether the investment originates in a worldwide country or a territorial country. In later chapters, we will consider separate estimation for different categories of FDI. 26 A foreign person’s U.S. income that is “effectively connected” with the conduct of a trade or business in the United States is subject to U.S. net—basis taxation. For more details, see U.S. Joint Committee on Taxation (I999). 27 Slemrod (19901:), p. i 78. 28 For example, Hartman (1984) argues that he ignores withholding taxes because they are relatively constant over time. 46 For the estimation of the overall tax effect on F DI in the U.S., I use the following specification. (1) log(FDIu): a0 + a) log(ETRp) + a2 log(BCA,) + a3 log(GDP,) + £61161: + up, where F D1,, = total foreign direct investment of industry i in year t, ET R), = effective tax rate of industry i in year t, BCA, = balance on current account in year t, GDP, = U.S. real GDP in year t. d, = industry dummy, u), = error term. The dependent variable is the log of foreign direct investment, and the main independent variable is the log of the effective tax rates. In general, when a variable is a positive dollar amount, the log is often taken. And when a variable is a proportion or a percent, there is a tendency to use them in level form”. But I make the independent variable (ETR: the effective tax rate) appear in logarithmic form, because the double-log specification has a nice property (the coefficient of the independent variable in the double-log model is an elasticity). I test whether the independent variable should take the logarithmic form or the level form using the Davidson-MacKinnon test”. The result of the Davidson-MacKinnon test suggests that the ETR can take either the logarithmic form or the level form. The coefficient a 1 in the above model is the elasticity of foreign direct 2° Wooldridge (2000), p. 135. 3° Wooldridge (2000), pp. 283-284. 47 investment with respect to the effective tax rate. I use both the average effective tax rate and the marginal effective tax rate as the independent variable, to see which effective tax rate measure has a better explanatory power in explaining foreign direct investment behavior. The rationales for the control variables are as follows: (a) Real U.S. GDP: Foreign direct investment in the U.S. may be influenced by U.S. economic conditions, and the economic conditions are measured by U.S. GDP. Therefore, I enter real U.S. GDP as a control variable. Econometrically, if U.S. GDP has some correlation with one of the explanatory variables, and if it has an effect on dependent variable (F DI), omitting the GDP variable will cause biased estimates. Hartman (1984), Boskin and Gale (1987), and Young (1988) also include a measure of aggregate economic activity in the U.S. as a control variable in their models,31 although they use nominal GNP. While they use nominal GNP, I use real GDP as the output variable. In the double- log specification, entering nominal variables instead of real variables in both the right- hand side and the left-hand side is the same as assuming that the price level is uncorrelated with the nominal variable on the right-hand side. I test for the correlation by including the log of the GDP-deflator in the double-log specification with the variable defined in nominal terms. It turns out that the price level is correlated with nominal GDP. Therefore, using the double-log specification with nominal F DI as the left-hand side variable and nominal GDP as the right-hand side variable causes the “omitted variable bias.” 3' Hartman (1984) and Boskin and Gale (1987) use log(FDI/GNP) as dependent variable in their models. This is equivalent to including log(GNP) as an independent variable, with a fixed coefficient of 1. 48 (b) U.S. balance on current account: Figure 6 compares the trend ofFDI in the U.S. and that of the U.S. balance on current account, during the 1979 — 1996 period. These trends suggest that a surge in FDI in the U.S. approximately coincides with a surge in the U.S. current-account deficit. This implies that foreign multinational companies invest a part of the surplus from trade with the U.S. in purchasing U.S. firms and establishing U.S. subsidiaries. In other words, FDI in the U.S. may have a negative relationship with the U.S. current account balance. Therefore. I include the U.S. balance on current account as a control variable. (c) Industry dummies: There are many industry-Specific factors, such as the capital-labor ratio, entry barriers, the market growth rate, and economies of scale, that determine the characteristics of an industry. These factors differ among industries, and they may influence the FDI. To control for these industry-specific factors that affect foreign direct investment, I include industry dummies. 49 Figure 6. FDI in the U.S. and the U.S. balance on Current Account: 1979 — 1996. 100.000 -~—--- -»-— --———--- —— . . .r--. - . ._ ___ _.._ ’ 50,000 -. o , ___Mi,-__ _.,- _- _.__,_ ,-_.___ ,2. _.__ _ ._-_--_-______ i1979 1980 1981 1 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 9 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 -50,000 . militlons of U.S. dollars 400,000 ' -150,000 ~‘ -200.000 1 — m.,*_ ~- w- w-- Sources: Economic Report of the President and Survey of Current Business. * ‘fdi’ and ‘bca’ stand for F D] in the U.S. and the U.S. balance on current account, respectively. 50 3. Data. For the estimation of the overall tax effect on F DI. annual data on foreign direct investment are needed. Earlier Studies that use the capital flow data analyze the overall tax effect on FDI with annual FDI data. However, the acquisition and establishment data by the BEA that I use are only available Since 1979, so I cannot get a sufficiently large number of observations. To avoid the problem from small number of observations, 1 disaggregate the annual FDI data by four industries: manufacturing, trade, finance and services, and other industries”. Table 6 shows FDI (the acquisition and establishment) data for the four industries. Table 7 and Table 8 Show my calculation of the average effective tax rates and the marginal effective tax rates for the four industries33 . The methodology and the data sources for my calculation of the average effective tax rates are provided in Chapter 2, and those for my calculation of the marginal effective tax rate are provided in Chapter 2 and an appendix. 32 I calculate the average effective tax rates on the basis of corporate income tax return data in Statistics of Income (80]) Bulletin published by the lntemal Revenue Service. So. my industry classification is restricted by the industry classification of the SOI Bulletin (eight industries: Agriculture-Forestry-Fishing, Mining, Construction, Manufacturing, Transportation and Public Utilities, Wholesale and Retail Trade, F inance-lnsurance-Real Estate, and Services). In addition, the FDI data in the Survey of Current Business have some data suppressions to avoid disclosure of data of individual companies. Therefore, to avoid losing too much information, I consolidate some industries into one industry. The four industries are (1) manufacturing, (2) trade, (3) services and FIRE (finance. insurance. and real estate), and (4) other industries. 33 Table 8 shows that the marginal effective corporate tax rates do not vary much among industries after 1987. This is because the marginal effective tax rate for equipment and that for structures are almost same after 1987. 51 Table 6. FDI in the U.S. by Industry: 1979-1996 (millions of U.S. dollars) Year Manufacturing Wholesale & FIRE & Services Others All Industries Retail Trade 1979 4,170 890 NA NA 15,317 1980 3,629 1.221 NA NA 12 172 1981 8.074 859 NA NA 23,219 1982 2,379 1.146 4,974 2,318 10,817 1983 3,1 13 293 3.995 690 8,091 1984 3,106 1,994 5,099 4,998 15,197 1985 12,140 2,021 4,925 4.020 23,106 1986 16,772 6,889 13,184 2,333 39,177 1987 19,751 2,483 15,088 2,988 40,310 1988 36,136 10.476 17,742 8,337 72,692 1989 35,958 4,495 22,932 7,776 71,163 1990 23,898 2,926 32,251 6,857 65,932 1991 11,461 2,228 10,862 986 25,538 1992 6,014 954 5,801 2,564 15,333 1993 1 1,090 2.332 9,707 3,100 26,229 1994 21,218 3,698 14,481 6,229 45,626 1995 26,643 4.006 19,669 6,879 57,195 1996 27,835 7,734 34,775 9,587 79,929 Source: Survey of Current Business. 52 Table 7. Average Effective Tax Rates by Industry: 1979-1996 Industry Year FIRE & Manufacturing Trade Services Others 1979 0.2681 0.2677 0.2656 0.1195 1980 0.2602 0.2754 0.2496 0.2783 1981 0.2579 0.3086 0.2600 0.31 17 1982 0.3514 0.3313 0.2797 0.3865 1983 0.2573 0.3031 0.2219 0.4128 1984 0.2510 0.2955 0.2524 0.3676 1985 0.2231 0.4044 0.2034 0.4097 1986 0.2530 0.4343 0.1727 0.5606 1987 0.2340 0.3679 0.2127 0.3822 1988 0.2043 0.2927 0.2172 0.2815 1989 0.2159 0.3505 0.2091 0.3697 1990 0.2274 0.4192 0.2083 0.4044 1991 0.2427 0.4012 0.2190 0.3926 1992 0.2287 0.3182 0.2178 0.3773 1993 0.2198 0.3048 0.2137 0.3356 1994 0.2248 0.2633 0.2075 0.3031 1995 0.2081 0.2907 0.1583 0.3058 1996 0.2058 0.2826 0.1759 0.2945 Source: Text. 53 Table 8. Marginal Effective Tax Rates by Industry: 1979-1996 Industry Year Manufacturing Trade FIRE & Others Services 1979 0.3668 0.4114 0.3996 0.3898 1980 0.4109 0.4437 0.4351 0.4279 1981 0.3293 0.3709 0.3600 0.3508 1982 0.3579 0.3910 0.3823 0.3750 1983 0.3195 0.3610 0.3501 0.3409 1984 0.3247 0.3657 0.3549 0.3459 1985 0.3120 0.3569 0.3451 0.3352 1986 0.2825 0.3358 0.3217 0.3100 1987 0.3223 0.3217 0.3219 0.3220 1988 0.3263 0.3252 0.3255 0.3258 1989 0.3350 0.3325 0.3332 0.3337 1990 0.3256 0.3245 0.3248 0.3251 1991 0.3279 0.3267 0.3270 0.3273 1992 0.3237 0.3229 0.3231 0.3233 1993 0.3407 0.3413 0.3411 0.3410 1994 0.3364 0.3376 0.3372 0.3370 1995 0.3412 0.3417 0.3416 0.3415 1996 0.3332 0.3348 0.3344 0.3341 Source: Text. 54 4. Estimation Results Because my data set has a cross-sectional component (4 industries) and a time- series component (18 years), I test for heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. I use the Breusch-Pagan test to test for heteroskedasticity“, and the AR(!) serial correlation test35 to test for autocorrelation. In the case of the regression of FDI on the average effective tax rate and other variables (equation (1) in section 2 in this chapter), I cannot reject either the homoskedasticity assumption or the assumption of no serial correlation at the 10% significance level. In the case of the regression of FDI on the marginal effective tax rate and other variables, I cannot reject either the homoskedasticity assumption or the assumption of no serial correlation at the 10% significance level. Table 9 summarizes the test results. Table 9. Test Results (total FDI on measures of the effective tax rate) Dependent Tax-rate Heteroskedasticity Autocorrelation Variable Measure p-value* AR(1)* * p-value* * * AETR No 0.73 No 0.19 0.13 log(FDI) METR No 0.11 No 0.18 0.16 * p-value of LM statistic ** estimate for the coefficient of AR( 1) model *"p—value of t statistic 3’ For the methods for testing for heteroskedasticity, see Wooldridge (2000), pp. 255-261. 35 For the methods for testing for serial correlation, see Wooldridge (2000), pp. 380-387. 55 Table 10 reports the results of the regressions of F DI on the average effective tax rate and other variables. Adding log(GDP) to the regression (column 2) reduces the tax elasticity to -0.74 and its significance level significantly to —l .26. And log(GDP) turns out to have a significant effect on log(FDI). This suggests that log(GDP) is a relevant control variable. Foreign investors appear to increase their direct investment in the U.S. when the U.S. economic situation is good and the GDP elasticity is about 2.5. Adding log(BCA)36 to the regression (column 3) increases the tax elasticity slightly to ——0.85 and its significance level to —1.45. And log(BCA) itself has a negative and statistically significant effect on log(FDI). This suggests that log(BCA) is also a relevant control variable. Foreign investors appear to decrease their direct investment in the U.S. as the U.S. current account balance improves. The specification in column four includes log(EX)37 as a control variable. The log(EX) does not make any difference. When log(EX) is introduced, the coefficients and t-values of the other variables remain almost the same. Column five and column six show the estimation results when the exchange rate, instead of the balance on current account, is controlled for. The exchange rate seems to have a negative effect on F DI (column 5). However, after including log(GDP) as an explanatory variable, the negative effect of the exchange rate on FDI is significantly ’6 ‘BCA’ stands for balance on current account. The balance on current account is actually positive in some years, and negative in others. To take the logarithm of the balance on current account, it is needed to make the smallest value of each year’s balance on current account have a value of one. 1 add a constant of $195,818 (millions of U.S. dollars) to each year’s balance on current account. Therefore, the estimated coefficients need to be interpreted with care. Hartman (1984), Boskin and Gale (1987), Young (1988), and Slemrod (1990) also use this transformation method. 37 ‘EX’ stands for the trade-weighted exchange rate. 56 diluted. The Sign of the coefficient is changed and its t-value is reduced quite significantly. And comparing the R-squareds in column two and column six, it is difficult to say that the log(EX) is a relevant control variable. According to my baseline specification (column 3), the elasticity of total FDI with respect to the average effective tax rate is —O.85. This estimate is not statistically significant at the 5% or the 10% significance level, but it is marginally significant at the 15% level (p-value: 0.15). And the estimation result tells that the sign of the FDI elasticity with respect to the AETR is not positive at the 10% significance level. The 10% critical value for a one-tailed test with 60 degrees of freedom is -1.296. The t-value of the FDI elasticity with respect to the AETR is —1.45. Therefore, the hypothesis that the F DI elasticity with respect to the AETR has a positive sign can be rejected at the 10% significance level. These results are consistent with the traditional view that foreign investors tend to undertake investment in the location with the higher after-tax rate of return. And these results are exactly opposite to those of Swenson (1994). She finds a positive and statistically significant effect of the average tax rate on foreign direct investment. 57 Table 10. FDI by Industry and the Average Effective Tax Rate* Dependent Variable: log oftotal FDI (in 1992 dollars) Independent Variables (l) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -1.74 -0.74 -0.85 -0.87 -1.33 -0.76 log(AETR) (-2.94) (-l.26) (-1.45) (-1.46) (-2.13) (-1.26) 2.62 2.56 2.67 2.71 log(GDP) _ (3.89) (3.88) (3.37) _ (3.35) -0.05 -0.05 log(BCA)” _ _ (-l.90) (-1.89) _ _ 0.18 -1.09 0.14 log(EX) _ _ _ (0.28) (-1.80) (0.21) industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.5516 0.6421 0.6627 0.6632 0.5745 0.6424 # of Obs. 66 66 66 66 66 66 * The number in ( ) is the OLS t value. AETR, BCA, and EX stand for the average effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the trade-weighted exchange rate, respectively. "”" log(BCA)=log(195,8 l 8+balance on current account). 58 To see which effective tax rate is a better explanatory variable for FDI behavior, I replace the AETR with the METR. Table 1 1 presents the results of the regressions of FDI on the marginal effective tax rate and other variables. As with the results from the regressions with the average effective tax rate, adding log(GDP) and log(BCA) to the regression (column 2 and 3) reduces the absolute values of the FDI elasticities with respect to the METR and their significance levels quite substantially. In fact, when both log(GDP) and log(BCA) are added, the METR variable has wrong sign. Whenever log(GDP) is included in the regression, the METR has a very small t-statistics. Therefore, it is impossible to say that the marginal effective tax rate has an important role in explaining the FDI behavior. These results suggest that the average effective tax rate is a better measure of tax burden than the marginal effective tax rate in explaining the variation of total foreign direct investment. The reason why the marginal effective tax rate is not a good explanatory variable for foreign direct investment will be addressed in Chapter 6. The specification in column four includes log(EX) as a control variable. The log(EX) does not make any difference. The coefficients and t-values of the other variables remain almost the same as they were when log(EX) was not included. This is the same as the result from the regressions of FDI on the AETR and other variables. Column five and column six show the estimation results when the exchange rate, instead of balance on current account, is controlled. The exchange rate seems to have a negative effect on F DI (column 5). However, after including log(GDP) as an explanatory variable, the negative effect of the exchange rate on FDI is greatly diluted. And comparing the R- squareds in column two and column six, it is difficult to say that the log(EX) is a relevant control variable. These results are the same as the regression results with the AETR. 59 Table 1 1. FDI by Industry and the Marginal Effective Tax Rate* Dependent Variable: log oftotal FDI (in 1992 dollars) Independent Variables (l) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -3.50 -0.63 0.27 0.36 -3.18 -0.69 log(METR) (-2.65) (-0.45) (0.18) (0.22) (-2.51) (-0.47) 2.81 3.05 3.14 2.73 log(GDP) _ (3 .90) (4.22) (3.16) _ (2.79) -0.05 -0.05 log(BCA)" _ _ (-1.70) (- l .68) _ _ 0.10 -1.43 -0.09 log(EX) _ _ _ (0.14) (-2.55) (013) industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.5409 0.6340 0.6510 0.6511 0.5858 0.6341 # of Obs. 66 66 66 66 66 66 * The number in ( ) is the OLS I value. METR, BCA, and EX stand for the marginal effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the trade-weighted exchange rate, respectively. " log(BCA)=log( 195,818+balance on current account). 60 CHAPTER V FDI IN THE U. S. AND THE INTERNATIONAL TAX SYSTEM OF THE INVESTOR COUNTRY 1. Overview of the International Taxation System38 International transactions, by their nature, entail a double-taxation problem that could result in a heavy tax burden for multinational enterprises. In general, there are two different approaches to avoiding the double-taxation problem. Some countries, such as the United States, the United Kingdom, Japan, and Italy, adopt the worldwide (or residence-based) system. Under the worldwide system, the home-country government taxes the worldwide income of its residents, and then allows a credit for foreign taxes paid on foreign-source income. The worldwide system is based on the principle that a tax system should not distort the investment location decision of a home-country firm (capital export neutrality). Other countries, such as France and the Netherlands, adopt the territorial (or source-based) system. Under the territorial system, the home-country government taxes only home-country-source income, and foreign-source income is exempt from the home-country taxation. The territorial system is based on the principle that there should be no discrimination within a country between domestic and foreign 3" For more details, see Ballard (1999). 61 investors, or between foreign investors from different countries (capital import neutrality). In the case of Canada and Germany, by statute, they adopt a worldwide system. However, by income tax treaty with the United States, Canada and Germany exempt U.S.-source income from its domestic taxation.39 Thus, Canada and Germany are considered to have a territorial system. from the perspective of foreign direct investment in the U.S. 2. The Response of FDI in the U.S. to the International Tax Regime The effect of a host country’s tax rate on inward foreign direct investment depends on the tax system of the foreign investor’s home country. For example, when the home country of the foreign investor has a territorial system, the effective corporate tax rate on FDI is equal to the tax rate imposed by the host country, because multinationals do not pay taxes on foreign-source income to the home-country government. Therefore, differences among host-country effective tax rates would be expected to have an effect on the investment location decisions of firms from territorial tax countries. The effect of the host country’s tax rate would be expected to have less influence on foreign investment from countries that have a worldwide system with a foreign tax credit. In a simple case without deferral“), if the host country’s tax rate is less than the home country’s tax rate, 3" Slemrod (1990b). p.179. 4° Under the worldwide system, a subsidiary’s profits are typically not taxed until they are repatriated to its parent firm, whereas a branch’s profits are taxed as they accrue. This is called deferral. Deferral in the worldwide system gives firms an incentive to accumulate profits in low-tax countries, rather than to repatriate them to its home country. For more details, see Alworth (1988), Altshuler and Newlon (1993), 62 the effective tax rate on FDI is the home country’s. but if the host country’s tax rate is higher than the home country’s tax rate (the firm is in excess-foreign-tax-credit position), the effective tax rate on FDI is the host country’s. Therefore. for firms from a worldwide tax regime, the effect of the host country’s tax system is filtered through the tax system of the home country, and may be substantially mitigated. Table 12 summarizes the relationship between the home-country tax system and the after-tax return on U.S. investments. Table 12. Home Country’s International Tax System and After-tax Return Home country’s international After-tax return on U.S. investments tax system Territorial RUS(1‘TUS ) RUS(1'TUS ) + RUS(TUS - TH) = RIJS(]'TII ) ifTus < TH RUS(1'TUS ) lfTUS > TH Worldwide 3. Empirical Results of Previous Studies According to the traditional view, it is expected that investment by territorial firms would respond negatively to an increase in the U.S. tax rate, and that FDI from worldwide countries should be insensitive to U.S. tax rates, or less sensitive to U.S. tax rates than F DI from territorial countries. On the contrary, the New View (associated with Altshuler, Newlon, and Randolph (1995). and Hines and Hubbard (1990). 63 Scholes and Wolfson (1990)) argues that worldwide investors should respond positively to the U.S. tax rate, while territorial investors should not be sensitive to the U.S. tax rate. Slemrod (1990) analyzes the effect of the home-country tax system on FDI in the U.S. He uses the capital-flow data for four territorial countries and three worldwide countries. He finds a significantly negative effect of U.S. taxes on F DI from only two countries (France, Germany) out of four territorial countries, and from only two countries (Japan, and the UK) out of three worldwide countries. In addition, he does not find any support for the prediction that FDI from territorial countries should be more sensitive to U.S. tax rates than FDI from worldwide countries. Slemrod interprets these results as meaning that, because multinationals take full advantage of deferral and sophisticated accounting and financial strategies, the home country’s system of alleviating double taxation is not an important determinant of FDI. Swenson (1994) uses the acquisition-and—establishment data for manufacturing- sector FDI from four territorial countries and two worldwide countries. She finds a positive and significant effect of U.S. taxes on F DI from worldwide countries. However, in the case of territorial countries. the tax effect is much smaller than it is for the worldwide investors, and it is rarely significant. These results conform to the prediction of Scholes and Wolfson (1992) that worldwide investors respond positively to the host- country tax rate, while territorial investors are not sensitive to the host-country tax rate. While Slemrod does not find any significant effect of the home-country tax system with the capital flow data, Swenson finds significant results supporting the argument of Scholes and Wolfson (1992) with acquisition and establishment data. This chapter investigates the effect of the home-country tax system on FDI in the U.S. with acquisition 64 and establishment data and with the average effective tax rate, which is different from that used by Swenson. 4. Model Specification and Data For the estimation of the effect of foreign investor country’s double-taxation-relief system on FDI in the U.S., I use the following specification. (2) log(FDIc, )= ap+ a;log(ETR,) + aglog(GDPJ + a 3 log(BCAa) + Zacdc + uc, , where F DIC, = foreign direct investment of country c in year t, E TR, = effective tax rate in year t, BCAC, = U.S. balance on current account with country c in year t, GDP, = U.S. real GDP in year t, d, = country dummy, uc, = error term. The dependent variable is the log of FDI of country c in year t, and the main independent variable is the log of the effective tax rate in year t. The rationales for the control variables are the same as those in the previous chapter, except for the country dummies. Country-specific factors, such as differences in language, differences in geographical location, and cultural affinity, might have an influence on the communication and information cost and the transaction cost of FDI. To control for these 65 country-specific factors, I include the country dummies. The data used in this chapter are slightly different from those used in the previous chapter. While the dependent variable in Chapter 4 was total outlays of FDI disaggregated by industry, it is total outlays of FDI from seven major investor countries in this chapter. The outlays of F DI by the seven major investor countries (XFDIC) account for about 70-80% of total FDI (XFDli). Table 13 shows the acquisition and establishment F D1 in the U.S. for seven investor countries. I use the annual average and marginal effective tax rates for all industries as the tax variable. Figure 7 presents my calculation of the annual average and marginal effective corporate tax rates of the U.S. I provide the methodology and the data sources in Chapter 2 and an appendix. For the estimation of equation (2), I use the U.S. balance on current account with each foreign investor country, instead of total U.S. balance on current account. The historical data on the U.S. balance on current account with major trade-partner countries are downloadable from the home page of the Bureau of Economic Analysis. Figure 8 shows the movements of the U.S. balance on current account with the seven major investor countries, along with F DI from the countries. 66 Table 13. FDI in the U.S. by Major Investor Countries: 1979-1996 (millions of dollars) Territorial Countries Worldwide Countries Year Canada France Germany Netherlands UK. Japan Italy 1979 1,414 262 2,436 4,955 2,511 257 NA 1980 1,956 600 1,424 1,650 3,066 596 97 1981 6,084 903 1,149 572 6,178 616 NA 1982 1,196 455 601 330 3,128 587 213 1983 1,072 295 584 492 2.366 392 NA 1984 2,587 330 685 562 3,714 1,806 45 1985 2,914 754 2,270 771 6,732 1,152 NA 1986 6,503 2,491 1,351 4,700 8,572 5,416 166 1987 1,276 2,044 4,664 391 15,142 7,006 268 1988 11,360 4,199 2,090 2,214 22,559 16,188 313 1989 4,403 3.469 2,435 3,629 23,047 17,410 436 1990 3,430 10,217 2,363 2,247 13,096 19,933 1,786 1991 3,454 4,976 1,922 1,661 2,169 5,357 435 1992 1,351 406 1,964 1,331 2,255 2,921 2281 1993 3,797 1,249 2,841 2,074 8,238 2,065 375 1994 4,128 1,404 3,328 1,537 17,261 2,715 412 1995 8,02 1,129 13,1 17 1,061 9,094 3,602 NA 1996 9,70 6,021 12,858] 6,476 14,757 8,813 NA Source: Survey of Current Business, various issues. 67 Figure 7. Effective Corporate Tax Rates in the U.S.: 1979 - 1996 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% .._. _. ..___4..___ _ .. .-i x_ x A . V v f 1979 1980 1981 I982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 year 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 + METR + AETR Source : text and appendix 68 Figure 8. The U.S. Balance on Current Account with the Seven Major Investor Countries Millions of U.S. dollars 14,000 and F DI from the Countries (Sources: Survey ofCurrent Business and www. 12000 -~ 10.000 8,000 6.000 4,000 - 2.000 - O -2.000 - 4,000 -' —6,000 ‘ -8,000 ' 12,000 10,000 8,000 6,000 « 4.000 < bea.doc. gov) CANADA -—BCA [ft-FDI ‘1—1979—Tn198‘0 7W;8.1.~T1982 ”198’ “T984798; 1988* 198 A “994 l 1995 " 1998 YEAR FRANCE J 1 i l—I—BCA l l—a—FDI Millions of U.S. dollars 2.000 < -2,000 4,000 1979 1980 1981 1982 198 1984 1985 1988 1987 198 1 69 Millions of U.S. dollars Millions of U.S. dollars 15.000 10,000 5,000 « -5,000 -10.000 . -15.000 -20,000 -25.000 20,000 A 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 —:-BCA -—i=oi YEAR Nethelands 18,000 4 16.000 14,000 < 12.000 . 10.000 4 8.000 . 6.000 4.000 2.000 A 1‘ l 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1987 YEAR 1988 1988 1989 1990 7O 25,000 20.000 10.000 5.000 Millions of U.S. dollars -10.000 < ' -15.000 ~20.000 15,000 4 -5.000 - L L A 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1-.g 3 1994 1995 1996 30,000 20,000 « 10,000 « 40.000 -30.000 Millions of U.S. dollars -50,000 -70.000 YEAR -20,000 « 40,000 1 -60,000 - 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1998 ' + total 71 3,000 2,000 1,000 -1.000 -3.000 Miilons of U.S. dollars 4,000 -5.000 4 -6.000 -2.000 4 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 72 5. Estimation Results Effective Tax rates and FDI of Territorial Investors To see how the foreign investor country’s double-taxation-relief system affects FDI in the U.S., I run regressions of FDI from the territorial countries and regressions of FDI from the worldwide countries on the effective tax rate measures, separately. Table 14 presents the estimation results of the regressions of FDI from territorial countries on the average effective tax rate. I test for heteroskadasticity and serial correlation, and it turns out that there is little evidence of heteroskedasticity or autocorrelation. Column two, column three, and column four show that adding log(GDP), log(BCA), and log(EX) do not have a great effect on the FDI elasticity with respect to the AETR for investors from territorial countries. These results suggest that the average effective tax rate is the most important factor for territorial investors’ investment-decision making. According to the estimation results from my baseline specification (column 3), the average-effective-tax-rate elasticity of FDI from territorial countries is negative (-3.5) and statistically significant (t-value: -2.69). This result is consistent with what is expected by the traditional view: territorial firms should respond negatively to an increase in the U.S. effective corporate tax rate. Table 15 reports the estimation results of the regressions of FDI from territorial countries on the marginal effective tax rate. Adding control variables changes the sign of the METR elasticity and reduces its statistical significance level quite substantially. According to the estimation results from my baseline specification (column 3), the marginal effective tax rate has little power in explaining the FDI behavior. 73 Table 14. F DI from Territorial Countries and the Average Effective Tax Rate* Dependent Variable: log oftotal FDI (in 1992 dollars) Independent Variables . (I) (3) (3) (4) (5) (6) -3.90 -3.47 —3.54 -3.18 -3.40 -3.13 log(AETR) (-4.62) (-2.66) (-2.69) (-2.37) (-3.64) (-2.34) 0.42 0.38 0.23 0.29 log(GDP) _ (0.43) (0.39) (0.24) _ (0.29) -0.06 -0.07 log(BCA)“ _ _ (-0.80) (-0.92) _ _ -0.66 -0.63 -0.61 log(EX) _ _ _ (-1.24) (-1.20) (-l .15) country dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.3669 0.3686 0.3747 0.3894 0.3804 0.3812 # of Obs. 72 72 72 72 72 72 * The number in ( ) is the OLS I value. AETR, BCA, and EX stand for the average effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the exchange rate, respectively. ** log(BCA)=log(26,320+ba1ance on current account). 74 Table 15. F DI from Territorial Countries and the Marginal Effective Tax Rate* Dependent Variable: log of total FDI (in 1992 dollars) Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -1.93 1.22 1.56 0.34 —2.34 -0.01 log(METR) (-1.47) (0.79) (0.97) (0.19) (-l.88) (-0.004) 2.82 2.94 2.05 1.93 log(GDP) _ (3.34) (3.42) (1.95) _ (1.86) -0.07 -0.07 log(BCA)” _ _ (-0.83) (-0.82) _ _ -0.88 -1.56 -0.89 log(EX) _ _ _ (-1.43) (-3.01) (-1.45) country dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.1909 0.3077 0.3149 0.3362 0.2937 0.3292 # of Obs. 72 72 72 72 72 72 * The number in ( ) is the OLS i value. METR, BCA, and EX stand for the marginal effective tax rate. the balance on current account, and the exchange rate, respectively. " log(BCA)=log(26,320+balance on current account). 75 Effective Tax rates and FDI of Worldwide Investors Table 16 presents the results of the regressions of FDI from worldwide investors on the average effective tax rate. Adding log(GDP) to the regression (column 2) reduces the absolute value of the AETR elasticity and its significance level substantially. And log(GDP) turns out to have a significant effect on log(FDI). Adding log(BCA) to the regression makes the AETR elasticity smaller, and reduces its significance level further. Log(BCA) also has a significant effect on log(FDI). These results suggest that the average effective tax rate is not an important factor for worldwide investors’ investment- decision making. According to the estimation results from my baseline specification (column 3), the average-effective-tax-rate elasticity of FDI from territorial countries is positive (0.45) but its t-value is quite small (0.25). This result is consistent with the expectation of the traditional view that FDI from worldwide countries should be insensitive to U.S. tax rates, or less sensitive to U.S. tax rates than F DI from territorial countries. Table 17 presents the results of the regressions of F DI from worldwide investors on the marginal effective tax rate. The estimation results from the baseline specification (column 3) show that marginal effective tax rate has little power in explaining F DI behavior. This result is similar to the result from the regression of territorial FDI on the marginal effective tax rate. Conclusion Comparing the elasticity of FDI in column (3) in Table 14 and that in column (3) in Table 16, we see that FDI of territorial countries responds negatively to an increase in the 76 U.S. average effective tax rate. while the response of FDI from worldwide countries to the U.S. average effective tax rate is insignificant. This finding is consistent with the expectations of the traditional view that the investment by the territorial firms would respond negatively to an increase in U.S. tax rate, and that F DI from worldwide countries should be insensitive to U.S. tax rates, or less sensitive to U.S. tax rates than FDI from territorial countries. Column three of Table 10 shows that overall FDI is negatively affected by the AETR (elasticity: -0.85), but the effect is only marginally significant. This estimate may be interpreted as a mingled effect of the results in Table 14 and Table 16. That is, the overall elasticity of FDI with respect to the AETR is the result of the combination of territorial investors’ sensitive response and worldwide investors’ insensitive response. Comparing the elasticity of FDI in column (3) in Table 15 and that in column (3) in Table 17, the marginal-effective—tax-rate elasticities of F D1 of both worldwide and territorial investors are statistically insignificant. So, we cannot say that the marginal effective tax rate has any relationship with F D1 of either territorial firms or worldwide firms. This finding suggests that the marginal effective tax rate is not a good explanatory variable for FDI behavior. This result is generally similar to the result from the overall analysis in Chapter 4, and the reason is addressed in Chapter 6. 77 Table 16. FDI from Worldwide Countries and the Average Effective Tax Rate* Dependent Variable: log oftotal FDI (in 1992 dollars) Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -3.45 0.77 0.45 0.44 -2.07 0.74 log(AETR) (-2.68) (0.42) (0.25) (0.25) (-1.56) (0.41) 4.23 3.87 3.06 3.29 log(GDP) _ (2.95) (2.75) (2.04) __ (2.15) -0.15 -0.14 log(BCA)“ _ _ (-1.89) (-1.76) _ _ -0.83 -1.44 -0.94 log(EX) _ _ _ (-1.43) (-2.51) (-1.58) country dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.6951 0.7463 0.7663 0.7774 0.7342 0.7656 # of Obs. 48 48 48 48 48 48 * The number in ( ) is the OLS I value. AETR, BCA, and EX stand for the average effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the exchange rate, respectively. ** log(BCA)=log(7l,747+balance on current account). 78 Table 17. F DI from worldwide countries and the Marginal Effective Tax Rate* Dependent Variable: log oftotal FDI (in 1992 dollars) Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -5.55 -2.46 -l.54 -l.93 -4.33 -2.77 log(METR) (-3 .39) (-1.24) (-0.76) (-0.96) (-2.72) (-1.42) 2.87 3.05 2.05 1.76 log(GDP) _ (2.48) (2.68) (1.58) _ (1.36) -0.13 -0.1 1 log(BCA)” _ _ (-1.66) (-0.46) _ _ -0.91 -1.41 -l.02 log(EX) _ _ _ (-1.55) (-2.74) (-1.74) industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.7187 0.7541 0.7691 0.7820 0.7656 0.7706 # of Obs. 48 48 48 48 48 48 * The number in ( ) is the OLS t value. METR, BCA, and EX stand for the marginal effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the exchange rate, respectively. " log(BCA)=log(71,747+balance on current account). 79 CHAPTER VI TYPES OF F DI AND EFFECTIVE TAX RATES This chapter seeks to find out the answer to the question raised in Chapter 4 and Chapter 5: “Why is F DI affected more significantly and strongly by the average effective tax rate than by the marginal effective tax rate?” Swenson (1994) estimates not only the effect of the average effective tax rate on F DI but also the effect of the marginal effective tax rate on F DI. She finds a positive significant effect of the AETR on FDI but a negative significant effect of the METR on FDI. She explains the negative METR-elasticity of F DI with the limitations of the METR itself. That is, she says that she does not accept the negative response of FDI to the METR as a reliable one, because she does not think the METR is a good measure of tax burden. In my own estimation, I find a positive (0.27) and quite insignificant (t-value: 0.18) coefficient. This suggests that the marginal effective tax rate has nothing to do with FDI. This chapter tries to present a systematic explanation for the relation between FDI and the measures of effective tax rates. In doing so, this chapter takes advantage of the industrial organization theories of FDI. This chapter also explores empirical evidence regarding the conjecture of Auerbach and Hassett (1993). They conjecture that establishment FDI could be affected by the marginal effective tax rate, but that acquisition FDI should not be affected by the marginal effective tax rate. The second goal of this chapter is to answer the question, “Does establishment FDI respond to the marginal effective tax rate?” 80 1. F DI and the Measures of Effective Tax Rates As is shown in Chapter 4 and Chapter 5, our baseline estimates indicate that F D1 in the U.S. does not respond significantly to the marginal effective tax rate. This phenomenon may be explained by considering the characteristics of F DI and the composition of F D1. While FDI is closely related to market imperfections, the concept of the marginal effective tax rate is based on the assumption of perfect competition. While most F D1 is accounted for by acquisition-type F DI (purchase of existing U.S. firms), the marginal effective tax rate measures the tax burden of a new investment project. This section discusses why the marginal effective tax rate has little power in explaining FDI behavior, in terms of the characteristics of FDI and the composition of FDI. 1.1. Characteristics of F DI Foreign direct investment is closely related to the concept of control and ownership and the special characteristics of multinational corporations (MNCs, hereafter). That is, in general, F D1 is undertaken by MN Cs for the purpose of obtaining control and ownership of a business in a foreign country. The fact that MNCs are undertaking FDI is very important in explaining the response of F D1 to the effective tax rates. According to modern theories of FDI, the monopolistic characteristics of MNCs enable or drive MN C5 to make FDI. Therefore, the marginal effective tax rate, which is based on the assumption of a perfect market, has limitations in explaining FDI, which is related to market imperfections. To make clear this point, it is needed to review the industrial organization 81 theories of F D1. 1 summarize the industrial organization theories of F DI, based on Graham and Krugman (1995), Casey (1998), and Caves (1996). The monopolistic advantage theory: Hymer (1976)“ and Kindleberger ( 1969) The monopolistic advantage theory explains how MNCs. which are in a disadvantageous position compared to local firms, are able to do foreign investment. A firm that undertakes investment in a foreign country faces some additional costs that a local firm, which is limited to the local market, does not incur. These costs are related to geographical distance between home and host country, exchange-rate risk, and differences in languages, cultures, technical standards, and customer preferences. For a MNC to overcome these disadvantages and invest in a foreign country, there must be some advantages over its local rivals. These advantages take the form of economies of scale or of superior technology. The conclusion of this theory is that FDI takes place because the MNCs have enough monopolistic advantages over their local competitors. The oligopolistic reaction theory: Knickerbocker (1973) The oligopolistic reaction theory tries to explain the observation that large U.S. multinationals tend to follow one another into foreign markets. A firm operating in an oligopolistic industry is compelled to follow its rival into a foreign market, even though the firm’s assessment of the expected profit of the project in the foreign market may not ¥ 4' Originally, Stephen Hymer’s Ph.D. dissertation was written in 1959. It was published posthumously in I 976. 82 be so good. This oligopolistic follow-the-leader behavior is motivated not by the desire to earn more profit, but by the desire to avoid getting shut out of a new market by an aggressive rival (leading firm). If the leader establishes a subsidiary in a foreign country, the rivals recognize that this investment might give the leader first-mover advantage and knock out their export business in the foreign country. These considerations dispose the rivals to imitate the leader and establish their own subsidiaries in the foreign country. The internalization theory: Buckley and Casson (1976) Internalization theory criticizes the ”monopolistic advantage theory,’ on the ground that it does not give an adequate explanation for why the MNCs choose F DI, rather than alternative modes of servicing the foreign market (such as export and licensing). According to internalization theory, for a MNC to service a foreign market via direct investment, rather than exporting or licensing, there must be some internalization advantage. That is, there must be economics for a MNC to exploit a market opportunity through internal operations rather than through exporting or licensing. These economies might be associated with costs of contract enforcement, or maintenance of quality or other standards. If these costs are absent, firms use licensing or exporting as a means of serving the foreign market. For example, a MNC can establish a subsidiary to maintain dependable suppliers of intermediate goods or to protect leakage of technology (maintaining technological monopoly). 83 The eclectic theory: Dunningfl 992) According to the eclectic theory, for FDI to take place there should be three advantages: ownership-specific advantages, intemalization-specific advantages, and location-specific advantages. Firstly, an MNC should possess some advantages that its local rivals do not have, such as product differentiation, advanced technology, and special marketing and managerial skills. Secondly, there should be some internalization incentives. That is, FDI should be more profitable than licensing or exporting. Thirdly, the foreign country should have some specific characteristics (e.g., low labor costs, abundance of raw materials, infrastructure, etc.) that can be linked with the other two advantages. For a MNC, which has owner-specific and intemalization-specific advantages, to invest in a certain country, the country must have some characteristics to attract the MNC. By reviewing the industrial organization theories of FDI, we can understand that FDI is closely related to market imperfections and that F D1 is a highly strategic behavior. Only firms with monopolistic advantages can undertake FDI. The firms in an oligopolistic industry may have incentives to undertake FDI. Maintaining technological monopoly is a source of market power in the product market, and thus it gives rise to an incentive to undertake FDI. In addition, FDI entails externalities. Examples include the introduction of new technology (e.g., just-in-time inventory method from Japanese automakers) and the 84 training of workers who may transfer their skills elsewhere”. So, we can conclude that FDI is closely related to market imperfections, and that FDI is a result of the strategic decision-making of a MNC. However, the concept of the marginal effective tax rate is based on the assumption of perfect competition and no uncertainty, and takes account of a very limited number of tax parameters. This discrepancy between the two can be an explanation of why F DI does not respond to the marginal effective tax rate. 1.2. Composition of FDI As shown in Figure 2 in Chapter 2, most F DI (over 80%) is accounted for by acquisition-type F D1. The preference for the acquisition mode can be accounted for by the advantages of acquisition-type FDI over establishment-type FDI. The choice between the acquisition route and the establishment route depends on the factors of time, risk, and the market for takeover. According to Caves (1996), the acquisition route is very quick and less risky than the new-establishment route. The MNC that buys the foreign firm also buys access to the valuable information and the existing distribution network of the foreign firm. It also acquires the local management team, who are aware of the local market environment. These factors reduce the risk of foreign investment. Of course, the acquisition is constrained by the availability of target firms. In contrast, the establishment route requires a long time to achieve the desired size and profitability, and it is much riskier than the acquisition route. ’2 Graham and Krugman (1995), p. 59. 85 If foreign investors, who are attempting to purchase an existing U.S. company or acquire some control over a U.S. company, were to consider the tax burden of the acquisition project, they would consider the current tax burden of the target company, not the tax burden from a new establishment project. However, the typical calculation of the marginal effective tax rate measures the tax burden of a new investment project. In addition, the marginal effective tax rate. which considers only a limited number of tax parameters, such as the investment tax credit, depreciation allowances, and the statutory tax rate, cannot capture all the factors that are relevant for acquisition-type FDI. In sum, while most F D1 is accounted for by acquiring existing firms, the METR measures the tax burden of a new investment project, considering only a few tax parameters. This logic can be another explanation to the question of why the marginal effective tax rate is not a good explanatory variable for F DI. In order to see if this hypothesis is correct, I run a regression of acquisition-type FDI on the AETR and on the METR separately. 1 use the following specification that is the same as equation (1) in Chapter 4, except for the dependent variable. The dependent variable is acquisition-type FDI. rather than total F D1. (3) log(Acquisition,,)= a0 + a) log(ETR,,) + a2 log(BCA,,) + a3 log(GDP)) + 201d. + up, where Acquisition), = acquisition type FDI of industry i in year t, ETR), = effective tax rate of industry i in year t, BCA, = balance on current account in year t, GDP, = U.S. real GDP in year t, d,- = industry dummy, up = error term. 86 Table 18 and Table 19 present the results ofthe regressions of acquisition FDI on the average effective tax rates and the marginal effective tax rate, respectively. Column three of Table 18 (my baseline specification) shows that after controlling for GDP and the U.S. balance on current account. the estimated elasticity ofthe acquisition FDI with respect to the AETR is —0.78. Thus, the sign and magnitude of this coefficient are consistent with my hypothesis that acquisition FDI is influenced by the average effective tax rate. However, the coefficient is not statistically significant (t-value: -1.12 and p- value: 0.27). With this estimation result, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the elasticity of acquisition FDI with respect to the AETR is zero. Column three of Table 19 shows the estimated elasticity of the acquisition F DI with respect to the METR is 0.23. Thus, this coefficient is not only small in magnitude, but it is also of the wrong sign. In addition, the coefficient is not even close to statistical significance. Its t-value and p-value are 0.13 and 0.89, respectively. Therefore, we can certainly not reject the null hypothesis that the METR elasticity is zero. My hypothesis is that acquisition FDI cannot be accounted for by the marginal effective tax rate, but can be accounted for by the average effective tax rate strongly. These results give at least some support to the hypothesis. Comparing column three of Table 18 and that of Table 19, the magnitude of the estimated elasticity of acquisition FDI with respect to the AETR is larger than that of the estimated elasticity of acquisition F DI with respect to the METR. The AETR elasticity is of the predicted sign, although’it falls somewhat short of statistical significance. The METR elasticity, however, is very small and quite insignificant. Therefore, I can say that the estimation results modestly support my hypothesis. At least, the empirical evidence is not against my hypothesis. 87 Table 18. Acquisition FDI and the Average Effective Tax Rate“ Dependent Variable: log of acquisition FDI (in 1992 dollars) Independent Variables (l) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -1.36 -0.66 -0.78 -0.79 -l .09 -0.67 log(AETR) (-1.91) (—0.94) (-1.12) (-1.11) (-1.48) (-0.93) 2.65 2.67 2.73 2.70 log(GDP) _ (2.99) (3.06) (2.72) _ (2.65) -0.05 -0.05 log(BCA)” _ _ (-1.63) (-l.62) _ _ 0.09 -0.94 0.08 log(EX) _ _ _ (0.12) (-1.24) (0.10) industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.4860 0.5638 0.5862 0.5864 0.5013 0.5639 # of Obs. 56 56 56 56 56 56 * The number in ( ) is the OLS t value. AETR, BCA, and EX stand for the average effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the trade-weighted exchange rate, respectively. *"' log(BCA)=log(l95,81 8+balance on current account). 88 Table I9. Acquisition FDI and the Marginal Effective Tax Rate* independent Dependent Variable: log of acquisition FDI (in 1992 dollars) Variables (1) (3) (3) (4) (5) (6) -2.84 -0.64 0.23 0.24 -2.98 -0.78 log(METR) (-l.80) (-0.39) (0.13) (0.13) (-1.94) (-0.43) 2.76 3.06 3.07 2.62 log(GDP) _ (2.92) (3.19) (2.47) _ (2.16) -0.05 -0.05 log(BCA)“ _ _ (-l.45) (-1.43) _ _ 0.01 -1.34 -0.17 log(EX) _ _ _ (0.02) (- l .87) (-0.19) industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.4820 0.5515 0.5758 0.5758 0.5157 0.5578 # of Obs. 56 56 S6 56 56 56 * The number in ( ) is the OLS I value. METR, BCA, and EX stand for the marginal effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the trade-weighted exchange rate, respectively. ” log(BCA)=log(l95,8]8+balance on current account). 89 2. Establishment F DI and the Effective Tax Rates According to the conjecture of Auerbach and Hassett (1993), establishment FDI could be affected by the marginal effective tax rate, but acquisition FDI should not be affected by the marginal effective tax rate. They state, “. . .the theoretical discussion and empirical analysis of the impact of taxation on FDI has treated the problem as one of acquiring new capital, even though this is only one of the possible modes. The mode of investment chosen affects tax liability differently because the choice to acquire a U.S. company will depend on the U.S. merger law governing, for example, step-up in basis and transfer of tax benefits, whereas investment in new capital will depend on the statutory tax rate, the investment tax credit, and depreciation schedules.”43 I agree with the second part of their conjecture, and I have explained this in terms of the characteristics of FDI (industrial organization theory of F DI). In addition, I have provided some empirical evidence that the acquisition FDI does not respond to the marginal effective tax rates, but modestly responds to the average effective tax rate. However, I do not agree with the first part of their conjecture. In principle, Auerbach and Hassett are making a valid point regarding establishment FDI. In principle, a marginal calculation is the correct one to make for a new establishment. However, in practice, the marginal effective tax rate is calculated under a set of very strong assumptions, so that the METR is not a very effective explanatory variable. My hypothesis is that the establishment-type FDI does not respond strongly to either the marginal effective tax rate (as measured) or to the average effective tax rate. ’3 Auerbach and Hassett (1993), p. 123. 90 First of all, why does the establishment FDI not respond to the marginal effective tax rate? Even though the establishment FDI is a new investment. the establishment F D1 is also a mode of F DI. That is, establishment FDI is also related to imperfect competition, and it is a highly strategic behavior. Therefore, by the same reason I explained in the previous section, the marginal effective tax rate is unlikely to be a good explanatory variable for establishment FDI. In addition, the effects of establishment F DI on an industry or market are different from those of acquisition F DI. In general, the acquisition route of FDI does not bring new capacity to the market in question. Of course, in some cases, the MN Cs may bring an expansion of production capacity by vitalizing the acquired company or enhancing the productivity. However, the establishment route of F DI adds production capacity to the market. It also entails some external economies - the creation of job opportunities and the training of workers. Therefore, each level of government in the U.S. offers investment incentives to foreign investors. Especially, state and local governments provide financial, tax, and other incentives to stimulate the local economy. These investment incentives might make the marginal effective tax rate faced by foreign investors different from the marginal effective tax rate calculated from some limited number of tax parameters. Consequently, the METR that can be calculated using available data may not capture some important aspects of the actual marginal incentives facing firms. Secondly, why does establishment F DI not respond to the average effective tax rate? As explained in Chapter 2, the average effective tax rate, which is defined as the ratio of taxes paid to net income, is a good measure of the tax burden of existing firms, but it cannot be a good measure of the impact of taxes on the incentives to make a new 91 investment. Accordingly, the establishment FDI, which is new investment in nature, does not respond to the average effective tax rate of existing U.S. firms. In sum, since establishment FDI is also related to market imperfections and strategic behavior, and it is attracted by special investment incentives, the METR cannot be expected to do a good job of explaining establishment F DI. And since establishment FDI is new investment, it is not to respond to the AETR. Therefore, neither the METR nor the AETR is expected to explain establishment (greenfield investment) —type FDI. To give support to my hypothesis, I discuss the foreign investment incentives programs provided by state governments in section 2.1. And to test whether my hypothesis is supported by empirical evidence, I try to estimate the elasticity of establishment F DI with respect to the AETR and that with respect to the METR in section 2.2. 2.1. Incentives to the Establishment FDI In general, the attitudes toward FDI of each level of government in the U.S. depend on the types of F DI. In general, most countries have a tendency not to welcome the transfer of ownership or control of domestic firms from domestic citizens to foreigners. Accordingly, acquisition of domestic firms by foreigners is restricted, or at least it is not promoted. For an extreme example, foreign control in nuclear energy, broadcasting, telecommunication, gas pipelines, and mining certain minerals and fuels is restricted in the United States”. However, a new investment, which adds production capacity and entails external economies of job creation and technology diffusion, is often promoted by ’4 Graham and Krugman (1995), pp. 122-123. 92 local governments. A number of state and local govemments in the United States provide a variety of investment incentives for foreign investors. The state and local governments provide these incentives to stimulate the local economies. Therefore, the primary targets of these incentives are the establishment-type F DI. rather than the acquisition-type FDI. The state and local governments do not consider the acquisition of an existing firm by a foreign investor as an investment that is eligible for the incentive programs, because it is nothing but a change of ownership. Graham and Krugman (1995) use an example of Honda Motor Company in explaining how state governments are eager to attract foreign direct investment. “. .. it was widely reported that at least three subnational governments — the state governments of Ohio and Pennsylvania and the provincial government of Ontario — competed to attract the large Honda Motor Company facility that eventually was located in Marysville, Ohio.”45 These investment incentives consist of various forms of tax relief, financial assistance, and provision of infrastructure and land free of charge. The following measures to attract foreign direct investment are excerpted from Poniachek (1986) and Casey (1998). (a) Financial assistance: Most states offer some type of financial aid to new investment within their borders. Many states have established loan funds and mortgage guarantee programs to help firms locating or expanding within the state. Four types of financing are commonly used - industrial revenue bonds and mortgages, loan guarantee programs, direct loan programs, and development credit corporations. ’5 Graham and Krugman (1995), p. 141. 93 (ti neg Cli (b) Tax incentives: Various kinds of State and local tax incentives are available on a negotiated or case-by-case basis. Among them are tax reductions and exemptions, tax credits, and preferential assessment. These are usually offered as exemptions or deferrals from property, inventory. sales, or income tax. Many states have enacted legislation to exempt new companies from various state taxes for specified periods. Some states provide a corporate income tax exemption for qualified companies. Preferred property-tax assessment is commonly applied to machinery and equipment. Business purchases may be exempted from sales tax. Reduced income tax is sometimes provided for out-of-state sales. and preferential income tax write-offs may be given for selected types of investment. (c) Infrastructure incentives: Infrastructure incentives include state government support of transportation, electric power, communications, and other forms of social overhead capital and public services, such as rail and highway connections, free land for industrial development, and low-cost sites in industrial parks. ((1) Training programs and labor incentives: These incentives include payment for the testing and screening of work-force personnel, and subsidies for job advertisements. Sometimes local educational institutions support curriculum efforts related to the needs of the incoming foreign companies. (e) Natural resource incentives: These incentives involve government assistance in providing foreign businesses with industrial resources such as land and energy. In areas where state environmental controls are more rigid than federal standards (e. g., pollution 94 control), exemptions or special exclusions to state law are sometimes granted to the foreign producers. All of these investment incentives provided by local governments make the expected tax burden of a new investment project faced by a foreign investor different from the marginal effective tax rate calculated with only a limited number of tax parameters. Therefore, establishment FDI is not expected to respond to the marginal effective tax rate, as the METR is usually measured. In conclusion, my hypothesis regarding the relationship between establishment FDI and the effective tax rates is that neither the AETR nor the METR will do a good job of explaining establishment-type FDI. In the next section. I present empirical support for this hypothesis. 2.2. Empirical Analysis To test my hypothesis, I run a regression of establishment-type F DI on the AETR and on the METR separately. 1 use the following specification that is the same as equation (3) in section 1 of this chapter, except for the dependent variable. The dependent variable is establishment-type FDI, rather than acquisition-type FDI. (4)10g(Establishment,,)= a0 + a) log(ETRp) + a2 log(BCA,) + a3 log(GDP)) + Edd,- + u,,, where Establishment,, = establishment-type F D1 of industry 1 in year t, E TR,-, = effective tax rate of industry 1 in year t, BCA, = balance on current account in year t, GDP, = U.S. real GDP in year t, 95 d,- = industry dummy. and u), 2 error term. Table 20 and Table 21 present the results of the regressions of establishment F DI on the average effective tax rates and the marginal effective tax rate, respectively. Column three of Table 20 (my baseline specification) shows that, after controlling for GDP and the U.S. balance on current account, the estimated elasticity of establishment FDI with respect to the AETR is —0.60, but it is not statistically significant (t-value: -1.01 and p-value: 0.32). With this estimation result, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the elasticity of establishment FDI with respect to the AETR is zero even at the 30% significance level. Column three of Table 21 shows the estimated elasticity of the establishment F DI with respect to the METR is —0.49, and that its t-value and p-value are -0.33 and 0.74, respectively. Therefore, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the elasticity is zero. Comparing column three of Table 20 and that of Table 21, the magnitude of the estimated elasticity of establishment F DI with respect to the AETR is slightly larger than that of the estimated elasticity of establishment FDI with respect to the METR. And the p-value of the METR elasticity is about two times higher than that of the AETR elasticity. The estimated elasticity of establishment FDI with respect to the AETR looks better than the estimated elasticity of establishment F DI with respect to the METR. Therefore, these estimation results do not strongly support my hypothesis that establishment FDI cannot be accounted for very well by either the METR or the AETR. However, I can say that the estimation results modestly support my hypothesis. While establishment FDI can only be explained very weakly by the AETR, establishment FDI 96 cannot be said to be explained by the METR. At least, the empirical evidence suggests that establishment FDI does not respond to the METR. which is opposite to what is expected by Auerbach and Hassett (1993). Columns three and four of Table 20 and Table 21 show that the balance of current account does not play a significant role in explaining establishment F DI. This is in contrast to the results in Table 18 and Table 19, in which the balance of current account is shown to have a marginally significant effect on acquisition F DI. This is an intuitive result. The balance-of-current-account variable is associated with the idea that, when the United States incurs a large current-account deficit, foreign investors are provided with a greater opportunity to acquire U.S. assets. This explanation of the role of the current account balance is more powerful in the case of acquisition investment than in the case of establishment investment. 97 Table 20. Establishment FDI and the Average Effective Tax Rate* Dependent Variable: log of establishment FDI (in 1992 dollars) Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -l.28 -0.58 -0.60 -0.54 -0.89 -0.52 log(AETR) (-2.09) (-0.99) (-1.01) (-0.90) (-l .45) (-0.87) 2.65 2.65 2.38 2.37 log(GDP) _ (3.58) (3.56) (2.79) _ (2.81) -0.01 -0.01 log(BCA)” _ _ 60.34) (0.38) _ _ -0.46 -1.36 —0.46 log(EX) _ _ _ (068) (-2.15) (069) industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.7871 0.8305 0.8311 0.8327 0.8051 0.8322 # of Obs. 56 56 56 56 56 56 "‘ The number in ( ) is the OLS I value. AETR, BCA, and EX stand for the average effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the trade-weighted exchange rate, respectively. ** log(BCA)=log(l95,818+balance on current account). 98 Table 21. Establishment F DI and the Marginal Effective Tax Rate* independent Dependent Variable: log of establishment F D1 (in 1992 dollars) Variables (ll (3) (3) (4) (5) (6) -2.75 -0.57 -0.49 -1.17 -2.93 -1.17 log(METR) (-2.03) (-0.41) (-0.33) (-0.72) (-2.31) (-0.79) 2.74 2.77 2.10 2.10 log(GDP) __ (3.48) (3.40) (2.00) _ (2.10) -0.004 -0.0002 log(BCA)* * _ __ (-0.15) (-0.006) _ _ -0.76 -1.70 -0.76 log(EX) _ _ _ (-1.03) (-2.88) (-1.06) industry dummies Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes R-squared 0.7861 0.8278 0.8279 0.8317 0.8165 0.8317 # of Obs. 56 56 56 56 56 56 "‘ The number in ( ) is the OLS I value. METR, BCA, and EX stand for the marginal effective tax rate, the balance on current account, and the trade-weighted exchange rate, respectively. ** log(BCA)=log(l95,8l8+balance on current account). 99 CHAPTER VII CONCLUSION (1) The estimation results of this dissertation (Chapter 4) suggest that overall foreign direct investment in the U.S. decreases 0.85 percent with a one-percent increase in the U.S. average effective tax rate. This estimate is not statistically significant at the 5% or the 10% significance level, but it is marginally significant at the 15% level (p-value: 0.15, t-value: -1.45). And the Sign of the FDI elasticity with respect to the AETR is not positive at the 10% significance level. The 10% critical value for a one-tailed test with 60 degrees of freedom is -1.296. Therefore. the hypothesis that the FDI elasticity with respect to the AETR has a positive sign can be rejected at the 10% significance level. These results are weakly consistent with the traditional view, in which foreign investors tend to undertake investment in the location with the higher after-tax rate of return. And these results are opposite to the new view, in which FDI responds positively to the host-country tax rate. In addition. I find that FDI does not respond to the marginal effective tax rate. The marginal-effective-tax-elasticity of FDI is close to zero (0.27) and statistically insignificant (t-value: 0.18). (2) The estimation results in Chapter 5 suggest that multinationals from countries with a worldwide tax system appear not to adjust their investment in response to changes in tax rates in the U.S., but multinationals from countries with territorial system reduce their investment in response to an increase in the U.S. average effective tax rate. The average- effective-tax-rate elasticity of FDI from territorial countries is negative (-3.54) and 100 statistically significant (t-value: -2.69). The average-effective-tax-rate elasticity from worldwide countries is positive (1.56) but statistically insignificant (t-value: 0.97). These results are consistent with the prediction of the traditional view that the investment by territorial firms would respond negatively to an increase in the U.S. tax rate. and that FDI from worldwide countries should not respond sensitively to the U.S. tax rates. These results are opposite to the argument of the new view, in which the worldwide investors respond positively to the host-country tax rate, and the territorial investors are not sensitive to host-country tax rate. (3) This paper also gives an answer to the question of why neoclassical investment theory (the cost-of-capital theory) cannot be easily applied to foreign direct investment behavior. I find the answers in the characteristics of F DI and the composition of FDI in the U.S. Firstly, F D1 is closely related to market imperfections, and F D1 is a result of strategic decision-making on the part of an MNC. However, the concept of the marginal effective tax rate is based on the assumption of perfect competition. Secondly, the calculation of the METR considers only a limited number of tax parameters. Thirdly, while most FDI is accounted for by acquisition of existing firms, the METR measures the tax burden of a new investment project. My estimation results weakly support the last point. The elasticity of the acquisition FDI with respect to the AETR is negative (078) and statistically insignificant (t-value: -1 . 12). But, the elasticity of the acquisition F DI with respect to the METR is close to zero (0.23) and statistically insignificant (t-value: 0.13). Although both the estimated AETR-elasticity and the estimated METR-elasticity are insignificant, the former appears to have better explanatory power than the latter. 101 flno-sfifi . .. (4) I test the conjecture of Auerbach and Hassett (1993): establishment FDI could be affected by the marginal effective tax rate. but acquisition FDI should not be affected by the marginal effective tax rate. I agree with the second part of their conjecture, and I explain this in terms of the characteristics of FDI and the composition of FDI in the U.S. However, I do not agree with the first part of their conjecture. My hypothesis is that establishment-type FDI does not respond to either the marginal effective tax rate or the average effective tax rate. Firstly, since establishment F D1 is also related to market imperfections and it is a highly strategic behavior, the marginal effective tax rate, which is based on perfect competition and considers only a few tax parameters, is unlikely to be a good explanatory variable for establishment FDI. Secondly. the average effective tax rate, which measures the tax burden of existing firms, is unlikely to be a good measure of the impact of taxes on the incentives to make new investment. That is, since establishment FDI is new investment in nature, it does not respond to the average effective tax rate of existing U.S. firms. And I find the empirical estimation results supporting my hypothesis. The elasticity of establishment FDI with respect to the AETR is negative (060) and statistically insignificant (t-value: -1.01). And, the elasticity of establishment FDI with respect to the METR is a little smaller (-0.49) and also statistically insignificant (t-value: -0.33). At least, we can say that establishment FDI does not respond to the METR, which is opposite to what is expected by Auerbach and Hassett (1993). (5) The difference between this paper and the earlier papers belonging to the traditional view is that this paper uses the acquisition and establishment data rather than capital-flow 102 data. As Young (1988), Auerbach and Hassett (1993), and Swenson (1994) point out. it is more appropriate to use acquisition and establishment data in explaining investment behavior. Even though this paper uses different data, the results of this paper are consistent with the arguments of the traditional view. The estimation results of this paper are exactly opposite to those of Swenson (1994). She finds a positive average-tax-rate effect on F DI, and she finds a positive average-tax effect on FDI by foreign firms from worldwide tax regimes, and an insignificant average-tax-rate effect on FDI by foreign firms from territorial tax regimes. The different point of this paper from Swenson (1994) lies in the calculation of the average effective tax rate. She uses average effective tax rates calculated by Tax Analysts, but I calculate the AETR based on the data in the Statistics of Income Bulletin by the lntemal Revenue Service. (6) In order to see what makes the results of this paper different from those of Swenson, I collect Swenson’s data set and replicate her estimation. As a result of replication, I find that the F DI elasticity with respect to the AETR turns out to be smaller (0.24) than her original number (0.75), and statistically insignificant. However, I find that there are some serious mistakes in her analysis that may make her results unreliable. One problem is that the average effective tax rate calculated by Tax Analysts may not be a good measure for the actual tax burden of U.S. firms. Tax Analysts calculate the average effective tax rate by using information in financial statements, and only the largest U.S. firms are included in their sample. Because there is some evidence that big firms engage in more deception, it does not seem that the Tax Analysts’ average effective tax rate is a representative U.S. average tax rate. The other problem is that Swenson uses Tax Analysts’ data very 103 arbitrarily in her analysis, by having the AETR of a subset of an industry represent the AETR of the entire industry. I redo the estimation with the corrected AETRs. The estimation results, using the AETRs for each industry calculated more appropriately, no longer support Swenson’s conclusion. I conclude that Swenson’s industry-level analysis suffers from the mismatching problem that the AETRS of large-digit industries are used to represent small-digit industries, and that it is hard to think Swenson’s estimation result is reliable. (7) The problems of the New View arise from its assumptions. The New View assumes that capital is perfectly mobile among countries and among assets. And it assumes that every adjustment process take place immediately. So, in the world of the New View, the economy is always in the equilibrium state. However, it is generally accepted that capital is not so mobile among countries and among assets. In the case of direct investment, capital seems to move slowly in response to a change in relative tax rate between countries and between assets. These capital movements, in turn, may lead to changes in asset prices and in the pretax returns of the assets. That is, the change in the pre—tax rate of return in response to a change in tax rate is the result of the process of capital movements. But, the New View thinks that every adjustment process occurs immediately, and the price and the pretax return change immediately in response to a tax change. And then capital (direct investment) moves again in response to these changes in asset price. Every problem of the New View seems to arise from this misunderstanding. 104 (8) Lastly, I want to point out that foreign direct investment is an investment itself. but it is significantly different from domestic investment in general meaning. In economic analysis, investment is defined as an increase in the capital stock of an economy or an increase in a fixed asset (PPE: property, plant, and equipment) of a business. However, foreign direct investment includes both the increase in capital stock by foreign investors and the transfer of ownership or control of domestic firms from U.S. citizens to foreigners. The most important portion of FDI is accounted for by the transfer of ownership or control. Therefore, in economic analysis, foreign direct investment should be treated differently from domestic investment. My estimation results, which suggest that the response of FDI to the marginal effective tax rate is different from the commonly expected response of investment to the marginal effective tax rate, can be explained by this characteristic of FDI. 105 APPENDIX 106 APPENDIX CALCULATION OF MARGINAL EFFECTIVE TAX RATES 1. Model The marginal effective tax rate measures what fraction of the real pretax rate of return to a new investment will be collected as taxes. The marginal effective tax rate accounts for tax benefits and penalties on income from a new investment that do not take the form of changes in the statutory tax rate. The calculation of the marginal effective tax rate assumes a perfectly competitive firm in a world with no uncertainty“. In a world without uncertainty a firm will invest a unit of capital up to the point where the present value of future receipts is equal to the cost of acquiring the asset. The model in this appendix draws on Gravelle (l 982)’s reformulation of the neoclassical model of Hall and J orgenson (1967). The rental price of capital services is defined by the equality between the cost of acquisition of an asset at time 0, and the present value of future rental prices. In the absence of taxes, this equality can be written as (A1) q = Jce'é’e”'e""””dt = c]e“”""dt 0 0 r + 5 ’6 Fullerton and Henderson (1987). 107 where q = acquisition cost. 6 = the rental price of a new unit of capital, r = the real return or discount rate, 7r= the expected inflation rate. and c5 = the rate of depreciation of asset. Rearranging terms, equation (A1) can be expressed as follows: 1 (A2) C = This means that the rental price is equal to the sum of the rate of return and the depreciation rate, for each dollar of capital (q is normalized to $1). In the presence of taxes, q can be written as follows. or: (A3) q = Ic(l — u)e‘5’e”'e'("’”)'dt + uq jD(t)e""’”"dt + kq 0 0 c(l — u)J'e"(""s)’dt + uqz + kq O C(I—u) = +uz+k , r*+5 C] q where u = statutory tax rate, 108 mfiflg‘nm-a-m~-n u. a. A 9‘! an... A o I ' I _ D(t) = depreciation deductions allowed at time I per dollar of investment, k = the investment credit rate. r* = the real after-tax discount rate, and z = present discounted value of depreciation allowances. Rearranging terms, equation (A3) can be expressed as follows: (A4) C_ q l—u When the equation (A2) and (A4) are combined, it is possible to express the real pretax return (r) as a function of the required after tax real return (r*), the economic depreciation rate (5), and tax variables (u, z, k): * (A5) rzr—l——+—5—(l—uz—k)—5 — ll The marginal effective tax rate is defined as follows: r—r* (A6) u* = —, where u* = marginal effective tax rate. 109 2. Tax Variables Statutory tax rate (u) Corporate income is subject to federal, state, and local income taxes. For the federal income tax, most corporations do not reach the top marginal tax rate, but the great bulk of corporate capital is held by firms that do. So I can model the top marginal corporate income tax rate as federal corporate tax rate.47 Jorgenson and Yun (1991) estimated state and local tax rates. Since the state and local tax rates show rising trends, I assumed 9% for 1987-1990 and 9.5% for 1991-1996. Because of the deductibility of state tax from federal tax, the combined tax rate can be estimated as follows: u = up(1-u5) + us, where u; is the federal corporate tax rate and us is the state corporate tax rate. Table A-1 shows my calculation of the statutory tax rates. Investment tax credit rates Before 1986, the tax code included an investment tax credit (ITC), which permitted a firm to subtract some portion of the purchase price of an asset from its tax liability at the time the asset was acquired. The TRA 1986 eliminated the investment tax credit. Table A-2 shows the investment tax credit rates by asset types. ‘7 See King and Fullerton (i984), p 202. 110 “WWI“ 7‘7, Table A-1. Corporate Income Tax Rates year Federal State and Local Federal, State. Local 1978 0.48 0.0645 0.514 1979 0.46 0.0657 0.496 1980 0.46 0.0724 0.499 1981 0.46 0.0773 0.502 1982 0.46 0.0885 0.508 1983 0.46 0.0863 0.507 .1984 0.46 0.0834 0.505 1985 0.46 0.0874 0.507 1986 0.46 0.0896 0.508 1987 0.34 0.0900 0.399 1988 0.34 0.0900 0.399 1989 0.34 0.0900 0.399 1990 0.34 0.0900 0.399 1991 0.34 0.0950 0.403 1992 0.34 0.0950 0.403 1993 0.35 0.0950 0.412 1994 0.35 0.0950 0.412 1995 0.35 0.0950 0.412 1996 0.35 0.0950 0.412 Source : Jorgenson and Yun (1991) and text. 111 Table A-2. Investment Tax Credit Rates Asset type 1978- 1 980 1981-1986 1987- EQUIPMENT Autos 3.3 6 0 Office/computing equipment 10 10 0 Trucks, buses, and trailers 6.6 10 0 Aircraft 7 10 0 Construction machinery 6.6 10 0 Mining/oilfield equipment 10 10 0 Service industry equipment 10 10 0 Tractors 9 10 0 Instruments 1 0 10 0 Others 10 10 0 General industrial equipment 9.1 9.6 0 Metalworking machinery 8.6 9.4 0 Electric transmission equipment 10 10 0 Communications equipment 10 10 0 Other electrical equipment 10 10 0 Furniture and fixture 10 10 0 Special industrial equipment 10 10 0 Agricultural equipment 10 10 0 Fabricated metal 10 10 0 Engines and turbines 10 10 0 Ships and boats 10 10 0 Railroad equipment 10 10 O STRUCTURES Public utility 10 10 0 Source: Gravelle (1994) and text. 112 Depreciation Allowances Historically, the United States has adopted various methods of depreciation: straight-line method, sum-of-the-years’-digits method (SYD), and declining-balance methods. Gravelle (1994) summarizes the depreciation methods adopted by the U.S. Table A-3 shows the depreciation methods historically adopted by the U.S. tax code. The straight-line method allows the taxpayer to deduct l/ T of the purchase price of the asset each year for Tyears. The asset is fully depreciated after T years. The formula of the present discounted value of depreciation allowances under the straight-line 4 . scheme 8 can be derived as follows: The declining-balance method allows the taxpayer to deduct a every year from .the remaining value of the asset, where a denotes the depreciation rate for tax purposes. For the double-declining balance method, the taxpayer can deduct a (=2/T) of the purchase price in the first year, and he deducts 2/ T of the remaining depreciation basis in later years. The formula of the declining-balance method49 is as follows: w z = Jae "“”’”dt = 0 a+ p ’8 King and Fullerton (1984), p. 20. ’9 King and Fullerton (1984), p. 20. 113 f For the sum-of-the-years’-digits (SYD) method. the taxpayer starts by calculating the sum of 1 through T. Let the sum be SUM. The taxpayer can deduct T/S UM of the purchase price in the first year, (T -1 )/S UM in the second year, and l/SUM in the last year. If T=3, for example, the purchase price is allocated as 3/6, 2/6, and 1/6 across the three years. Under the SYD scheme, the asset is fully depreciated, as under the straight-line scheme. The formula can be derived as follows: 'I‘ T 2 = ]——.——e(€ _ 1) “”dt = 3—]e"”dt — 2, jte‘p’dt 0 T 0 T. 0 Jtdt O _ ~eT -eT_ =30 e )+ 2. T p?” p 2 1 —)l' =——1—— 1— ‘ pTl th e )1 If we know the value of p and T, we can calculate the present discounted value of depreciation allowances under each method. The discount rate (p) of the corporations is the sum of the real after-tax discount rate (r*) and the expected inflation rate (it). The real after-tax discount rate is equal to a weighted average of the rate of return on debt and equity”: r*=f(i(l-uF)-1t)+(l-f)E, 5° See Gravelle (1994), p. 291. 114 where f is the fraction financed by debt. i is nominal interest rate, up is the corporate statutory tax rate, and E is the return required by stockholders prior the personal level taxes. 115 Table A-3. Depreciation Methods Asset type Year Depreciation Methods Equipment 1978-80 SYD (including Public Utility 1981 Double declining balance Structures) 1982-86 150% declining balance 1987- 3, 5, 7, 10-year class; double declining balance 15, 20-year class; 150% declining balance Structures 1978-80 Nonresidential structures; 150% declining balance Residential; SYD 1981-86 175% declining balance 1987- Straight line Source: Gravelle (1994). 116 qfsrrff _ «-.m _' 3. Expected Inflation Rate In calculating the marginal effective tax rate, Hendershott & Hu (1981) calculate the expected inflation rate using the adaptive expectations model (a geometric weighted average of inflation of the previous seven quarters). Gravelle (1994) uses the expected inflation rates of the Drexel-Bumham-Lambert Decision Makers Poll for the period 1979-1989, and those calculated, based on Hendershott and Hu’s adaptive expectations model, for the period 1953-1978. The data of the Drexel-Bumham-Lambert Decision Makers P011 is no longer available since 1989. And the adaptive expectation model has lost its theoretical reliability. So, I use the Livingston Survey data, which is historical data on the expected inflation rates maintained by the Federal Reserve Bank (FRB) of Philadelphia. The F RB of Philadelphia collects forecasts of inflation and other economic variables from economists in academic profession and business. The Livingston Survey data are frequently used in empirical studies in macroeconomics5 1. Table A-4 compares the expected inflation rates from the Livingston Survey and actual inflation rates. For the years 1979-1981 and 1988-1991, the actual inflation rates were higher than the expected inflation rates. And for the years 1982-1987 and 1992-1996, the actual inflation rates were lower than the expected inflation rates. 5' For example, Clarida (2000). 117 Table A-4. Comparison of the expected and actual inflation rates Livingston Survey Year (CPI) Actual CPI Actual GDP Deflator 1979 70% 11.3497 8.5 1980 9.629 13.4986 9.2 1981 10.269 10.3155 9.4 1982 7.198 6.1606 6.3 1983 5.131 3.2124 4.3 1984 5.319 4.3173 3.8 1985 4.781 3.5611 3.4 1986 3.954 1.8587 2.6 1987 3.689 3.6496 3.1 1988 4.095 4.1373 3.7 1989 4.769 4.8183 4.2 1990 3.964 5.4032 4.3 1991 3.835 4.2081 4 1992 3.364 3.0103 2.8 1993 3.387 2.9936 2.6 1994 3.183 2.5606 2.4 1995 3.469 2.8340 2.3 1996 2.879 2.9528 1.9 118 Sources: Economic Report of the President and www.phil.frb.org. 4. Other Variables Hulten and Wykoff (1981) estimate the economic depreciation rates for 34 asset categories. For the economic depreciation rates for each asset, I assume that Hulten and Wykoff (1981)’s estimated values still hold. Gravelle (1994) recalculates the economic depreciation rates for 28 asset categories based on Hulten and Wykoff’s estimated values. Gravelle (1994)’s economic depreciation is presented in Table A-5. Lifetime of assets is reported in Table A-6. For nominal interest rates, I use Baa bond rates from Economic Report of the President 1999.52 For the required return to stockholders prior to personal taxes, I set it equal to the real after-tax rate of return, plus a risk premium of 4 percent.53 5’ See Gravelle (1994), p. 293. ’3 See Gravelle (1994), pp. 291-293. 119 Table A-5. Economic Depreciation Rates Asset Type Economic Depreciation Rate EQUIPMENT 1. Autos 0.3333 2. Office/computing Equipment 0.2729 3. Trucks, Buses, and Trailers 0.2537 4. Aircraft 0.1818 5. Construction machinary 0.1722 6. Mining/oilfield equipment 0.1650 7. Service industry equipment 0.1650 8. Tractors 0.1633 9. Instruments 0.1473 10. Others 0.1473 1 1. General industrial equipment 0.1225 12. Metalworking machinery 0.1225 13. Electric transmission Equipment 0.1 179 14. Communications equipment 0.1179 15. Other electrical equipment 0.1 179 16. Furniture and fixtures 0.1 100 17. Special industrial equipment 0.1031 18. Agricultural equipment 0.0971 19. Fabricated metal 0.0971 20. Engines and turbines 0.0786 21. Ships and boats 0.0750 22. Railroad equipment 0.0660 STRUCTURE 1. Others 0.0663 2. Industrial 0.0454 3. Public utility 0.033 4. Commercial 0.0316 5. Farm 0.0230 6. Residential 0.0237 Source: Gravelle (1994). 120 Table A-6. Asset Lifetimes Asset type 78-80 81 82-83 84-86 87-92 93- EQUIPMENT Autos 3 2.5 2.5 2.5 5 5 Office/computing equipment 7 4.5 4.5 4.5 5 5 Trucks, buses, and trailers 5 4.5 4.5 4.5 5 5 Aircraft 9.2 4.5 4.5 4.5 6.8 6.8 Construction machinery 5 4.5 4.5 4.5 5 5 Mining/oilfield equipment 9.2 4.5 4.5 4.5 7 7 Service industry equipment 9.9 4.5 4.5 4.5 7 7 Tractors 7.1 4.5 4.5 4.5 6.4 6.4 Instruments 10.3 5.1 5.1 5.1 5( 12%) 5(12%) 7(81%) 7(81%) 20(7%) 20(7%) Others 8.8 4.5 4.5 4.5 7 7 General industrial equipment 9.9 4.9 4.9 4.9 3(4%) 3(4%) 5( 14%) 5(14%) 7(73%) 7(73%) 20(9%) 20(9%) Metalworking machinery 7.8 4.2 4.2 4.2 6.7 6.7 Electric transmission equipment 13.8 7.3 7.3 7.3 5(5%) 5(5%) 7(53%) 7(53%) 20(42%) 20(42%) Communications equipment I 1.5 4.5 4.5 4.5 5 5 Other electrical equipment 9 4.5 4.5 4.5 7 7 Furniture and fixture 8 4.5 4.5 4.5 7 7 Special industrial equipment 9.2 4.5 4.5 4.5 6.5 6.5 Agricultural equipment 8 4.5 4.5 4.5 7 7 Fabricated metal 14.2 6.6 6.6 6.6 5(18%) 5(18%) 7(40%) 7(40%) 20(42%) 20(42%) Engines and turbines 18.1 10.8 10.8 10.8 15(25%) 15(25%) 2(75%) 2(75%) Ships and boats 16 4.5 4.5 4.5 10 10 Railroad equipment 15 9.5 9.5 9.5 7 7 STRUCTURES Others 31 15 18 19 31.5 39 Industrial 36 15 18 I9 3 1.5 39 Public utility 22 12.9 12.9 12.9 15(25%) 15(25%) 2(75%) 2(75%) Commercial 37 15 18 19 31.5 39 Farm 20 15 18 19 20 20 Residential 31 15 18 19 27.5 27.5 Source: Gravelle (1994). 121 5. Calculation I calculate marginal effective tax rates for 28 assets, using the information described above. Then I calculated the METR for two broad assets (equipment and structures). I use Gravelle (1994)’s asset share calculation (Table A-7). To calculate the METR by industry, appropriate weights are needed. I use Gravelle (1994)’s capital stock share (Table A-8) as the weights. My calculation of the METR for 4 industries is presented in Table 8 in Chapter 4. 122 Table A-7. Asset Share Asset type Asset Share EQUIPMENT Autos 4.6 Office/computing equipment 5.0 Trucks, buses, and trailers 8.3 Aircraft 1.9 Construction machinery 3.4 Mining/oilfield equipment 1.7 Service industry equipment 3.2 Tractors 2.9 Instruments 6.5 Others 2.7 General industrial equipment 6.8 Metalworking machinery 6.7 Electric transmission equipment 5.4 Communications equipment 10.5 Other electrical equipment 1.8 Furniture and fixture 5.8 Special industrial equipment 6.6 Agricultural equipment 4.9 Fabricated metal 3.3 Engines and turbines 2.0 Ships and boats 2.3 Railroad equipment 4.4 STRUCTURES Mining 7.6 Others 1.3 Industrial 16.7 Public utility 27.8 Commecial 40.6 Farm 6.1 Source: Gravelle (1994). 123 Table A-8. Capital Stock Share by Industry Industry Equipment Structures Agriculture 0.479 0.521 Mining 0.389 0.611 Construction 0.83 8 0.162 Transportation 0.766 0.234 Public Utility 0.174 0.826 Trade 0.299 0.701 Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate 0.354 0.646 Services 0.354 0.646 Manufacturing 0.508 0.402 Food 0.444 0.556 Chemicals 0.557 0.443 Metal 0.540 0.460 Machinery 0.53 1 0.469 Other Manufacturing 0.495 0.505 Source : Gravelle (1982). 124 .5341". or} 7".3. Ls... LIST OF REFERENCES F.7- r l REFERENCES Altshuler, Rosanne, and T. Scott Newlon (1993), “The Effects of U.S. Tax Policy on the Income Repatriation Patterns of U.S. Multinational Corporations.” In Studies in International Taxation, edited by Alberto Giovanini. Glenn Hubbard, and Joel Slemrod: 77-114. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Altshuler, Rosanne, T. Scott Newlon, and William C. Randolph (1995), “Do Repatriation Taxes Matter? Evidence from the Tax Returns of U.S. Multinationals.” In The Eflects of Taxation on Multinational Corporations. edited by Martin Feldstein. James R. Hines, Jr., and R. Glenn Hubbard: 253-276. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Alworth, Julian S. (1988), The Finance, Investment and Taxation Decisions of Multinationals. New York: Basil Blackwell. Auerbach, Alan J., and Kevin Hassett (1993), “Taxation and Foreign Direct Investment in the United States: A Reconsideration of the Evidence.” In Studies in International Taxation, edited by Alberto Giovanini, Glenn Hubbard, and Joel Slemrod: 119-147. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Auerbach Alan J., and David Reishus (1988), “The Impact of Taxation of Mergers and Acquisitions.” In Mergers and Acquisitions, edited by Alan J. Auerbach: 69-85. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Auerbach, Alan J., and Joel Slemrod (1997), “The Economic Effects of the Tax Reform Act of 1986.” Journal of Economic Literature 35: 589-623. Ballard, Charles L. (1999), “International Aspects of Fundamental Tax Reform.” Mimeo, Michigan State University (November 23). Boskin, Michael, and William G.Gale (I 987), “New Results on the Effect of Tax Policy on the International Location of Investment.” In The Effect of Taxation on the Capital Accululation, edited by Martin Feldstein: 201-19. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 126 Buckley, Peter J ., and Mark C. Casson (1976), The Future of Multinational Enterprise, London: Macmillan. Casey, William L. (1998), Beyond the Numbers: Foreign Direct Investment in the United States. London: Jai Press. Caves, Richard E. (1996), Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Clarida, Richard (2000). “Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: Evidence and some theory.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, February: 147-180. Dunning, John H. (1992), Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Addison- Wesley Publishing Company. F ahim-Nader. Mahnaz (1999), “Foreign Direct Investment in the United States.” Survey of Current Business, June: 29-3 7. Feldstein, Martin, and Philippe Bacchetta (1990), “National Saving and International Investment.” In National Saving and Economic Performance, edited by B. Douglas Bemheim and John B. Shoven: 201-226. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Feldstein, Martin S., and Horioka Charles (1980), “Domestic Savings and International Capital Flows.” Economic Journal, June: 314-329. Frankel, Jeffrey A. (1990), “Quantifying lntemational Capital Mobility in the 19805.” In National Saving and Economic Performance, edited by B. Douglas Bemheim and John B. Shoven: 227-270. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Fullerton, Don (1984), “Which Effective Tax Rate.” National Tax Journal 37: 23-41. Fullerton, D., and Y. K. Henderson (1987), “The Impact of Fundamental Tax Reform on the Allocation of Resources.” In The Eflects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation, edited by M. Feldstein: 401-443. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 127 Gordon, Roger H., and A. Lans Bovenberg (1996), “Why is capital so immobile internationally? Possible explanations and implications for capital income taxation.” American Economic Review, December: 1057-1075. Graham, Edward M., and Paul R. Krugman (1995), Foreign Direct Investment in the United States. Washington, DC: Institute for lntemational Economics. Gravelle, Jane G. (1982), “Effects of the 1981 Depreciation Revision on the Taxation of Income from Business Capital.” National Tax Journal 35: 1-20. Gravelle, Jane G. (1994). The Economic Effects of Taxing Capital Income. Cambridge, Massachusetts: The MIT Press. Hall, Robert E., and Dale W. Jorgenson (1967), “Tax Policy and Investment Behavior.” American Economic Review 5 7: 391-414. Hartman, David G. (1981), Domestic Tax Policy and Foreign Investment: Some Evidence, NBER Working Paper no. 784, Cambridge, Mass: National Bureau of Economic Research. Hartman, David G. (1984), “Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment in the United States.” National Tax Journal 37: 475-87. Hartman, David G. (1985), “Tax Policy and Foreign Direct Investment.” Journal of Public Economics 26: 107-21 . Hendershott, Patric H., and Sheng-Cheng Hu (1981), “Investment in Producer’s Equipment.” In How Taxes A fleet Economic Behavior, edited by Aaron, Henry J., and Joseph A. Pechman: 85-129. Washington DC: The Brookings Institution. Hines, James R. (1999), “Lessons from Behavioral Responses to lntemational Taxation.” National Tax Journal, June: 305-322. Hines, James R., Jr., and R. Glenn Hubbard (1990), “Coming Home to America: Dividend Repatriations by U.S. Multinationals.” In Taxation in the Global Economy, edited by Assaf Razin and Joel Slemrod: 161-207. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 128 Hulten, Charles R., and Frank C. Wykoff (1981), “The Measurement of Economic Depreciation.” In Depreciation, Inflation, and The Taxation of Incomefrom Capital, edited by Charles R. Hulten: 81-170, Washington, DC: The Urban Institute Press. Hymer, Stephen H. (1976), The International Operations of National F irms, MA: MIT Press. Jorgenson, Dale W., and Kun-Young Yun (1991), Tax Reform and the Cost ofCapital. London: Clarendon Press. Kindleberger, Charles P. (1969), American Business Abroad: Six Lectures on Foreign Direct Investment. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. King, Mervin A., and Don Fullerton (1984), The Taxation of Income from Capital. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Knickerbocker, Frederick T. (1973), Oligopolistic Reaction and Multinational Enterprise. Boston: Harvard University Graduate School of Business Administration. MacDougall, G.D.A. (I960), “The Benefits and Costs of Private Investment from Abroad: A Theoretical Approach.” Economic Record, March: 13-35. Manzon, Jr., Gil B., and George A. Plesko (2001), “The Relationship Between Financial and Tax Reporting Measures of Income.” Mimeo, Massachusetts Institute of Technology (January). Mishkin, Frederic S. (1984), “Are Real Interest Rates Equal Across Countries? An Empirical Investigation of lntemational Parity Conditions.” Journal of Finance, December: 1345-1357. Moody, Scott (1998), Special Report: The Federal Corporate Income Tax Since World War 11. Washington DC: Tax Foundation. Obstfeld, Maurice (1993), “International Capital Mobility in the 1990s.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 4534 (November). 129 Poniachek, Harvey A.(l986), Direct Foreign Investment in the United States. Lexington, Mass: D.C. Heath and Company. Quijano, Alicia M. (1990), “A guide to BEA statistics on foreign direct investment in the United States.” Survey of Current Business. January. Scholes, Myron S., and Mark A. Wolfson (1992), Taxes and Business Strategt Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Slemrod, Joel (1990), “Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investment in the United States: Evidence from a Cross-country Comparison.” In Taxation in the Global Economy, edited by Assaf Razin and Joel Slemrod: 79-117. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Swenson, Deborah (1994), “The Impact of U.S. Tax Reform Act on Foreign Direct Investment in the United States.” Journal of Public Economics 54: 243-66. Tax Analysts (1986), Effective Corporate Tax Rates 1980-1 984. Arlington, VA. Tax Analysts (1986), Effective Corporate Tax Rates 1985. Arlington, VA. Tax Analysts (1987), Effective Corporate Tax Rates 1986. Arlington, VA. Tax Analysts (1988), Effective Corporate Tax Rates 198 7. Arlington, VA. Tax Analysts (1990), Effective Corporate Tax Rates 1988. Arlington, VA. Tax Analysts (1991), Effective Corporate Tax Rates 1989. Arlington, VA. Tayor, Herb (1992), “The Livingston Surveys: A History of Hopes and Fears.” Business Review, January/February: 15-27. U.S. Joint Committee on Taxation (1999), Description and Analysis of Present-Law Rules Relating to International Taxation. U.S. Council of Economic Advisers (1999), Economic Report of the President. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. 130 U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis (various years), Survey of Current Business. Washington DC. U.S. Department of Treasury (1999), “The Problems of Corporate Tax Shelters: Discussion, Analysis and Legislative Proposals.” Washington, DC: U.S. GPO. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (2000), Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach. Cincinnati, Ohio: South-Western College Publishing. Young, Kan H. (1988), “The Effects of Taxes and Rates of Return on Foreign Direct Investment in the United States.” National Tax Journal 41: 109-21. 131 illiliiiiiliilliiiittlili