LEBRARY Michigan State University PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. TO AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE -m 10 51 389% -x—%-8-£”A Ltd I U3 Wm H U3 U A; "FEB'T'U 2008 496’fim‘fi 1 93 2 5 o 8 6101 chlRC/DateDuepGS—pJS RESOURCE ACCOUNTING FRAMEWORK FOR THE COMMUNITY-BASED FOREST MANAGEMENT SYSTEM OF THE PHILIPPINES: A CASE STUDY By Gem B. Castillo A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Forestry 2001 ABSTRACT RESOURCE ACCOUNTING FRAMEWORK FOR THE COMMUNITY-BASED FOREST MANAGEMENT SYSTEM OF THE PHILIPPINES: A CASE STUDY By Gem B. Castillo This study presents a natural resource accounting framework at the community level that captures non-marketed components and natural resource exploitation not captured by conventional accounts. The conceptual framework consists of a rural/community-households' economic system, a natural resource system simulation model, and a social accounting matrix (SAM). The empirical study was conducted in five communities bordering the Bicol National Park in Region V, Bicol Region, in the Philippines. Focus group discussions and face-to-face interviews of households elicited data on consumption and production activities. The household survey sampled 20% of households in the five communities. Empirical data consisted mostly of consumption and production activities, transformed to monetary terms, and structured in the SAM framework. Non-marketed outputs comprised 21.3% of total production. Forest resources represented 27.1% of the total production. Natural resources data in the SAM became the basis for developing the simulation model for evaluating resource sustainability. Current wood consumption would cause natural resources depreciation by 0.07% per year while the proposed harvest would cause depreciation by 4.21%. The developed framework captures the rural economic system and is useful for policy evaluation and decision- making at the local level. The natural resource accounting structure supplements the national accounts by providing both marketed and non-marketed transactions at the community level. The natural resource modeled in the study focused on timber. Future study could incorporate sustainability models for other non-timber resources such as rattan, bamboo, medicinal plants. Copyright by GEM B. CASTILLO 2001 To a friend I dearly love; my thoughts of whom filled my mind as i wrote this manuscript. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Dr. Larry A. Leefers, my major professor and academic adviser, for the consistent guidance, help with personal concerns, funding, patience and careful instructions; Dr. Jianguo Lou, for lessons in simulation and modeling and providing helpful comments on the dissertation including the the proposal; Dr. Karen Potter-Witter, as mentor who is willingness to provide appropriate materials in the course of the study; Dr. Daniel Stynes, providing help in research methods and valuable inputs into the dissertation and proposal; Dr. Marian S. delos Angeles, for motivation to go ahead with natural resource accounts at the community level, facilitating and funding of the field research; Dr. Daniel E. Keathley, for providing financial assistance for travel, and completion of dissertation; Dr. Richard Brandenburg, Dr. William Taylor, and the Graduate School for providing the Dissertation Completion Fellowship; The Thoman Fellow Program for giving me the fellowship; Dr. Donald 1. Dickmann, for lessons on research methods and able support as mentor while conducting work at the department as graduate research assistant; Dr. Mike Vasievich for providing graduate assistantship funds while taking courses; Drs. Bruce Harker and Ernie Guiang of the Development Alternatives Inc. - Natural Resources Management Program for funding of the field research; vi Field interviewers (Rommel, Gemma, F rocy, Belen, Tuks, Buddy, Orlie, and Yolly); Officers of ENRAP (Joe Padilla et al.), NRMP (Elmer Boncares et al.), and DENR (Yumi Quintos et al.); and barangay officials of San Pascual, Pambuhan, Tarum, Colasi and Tible; Rex, Vangie and John Daniel, Tito, Marita and Maya who during most difficult times supported me wholeheartedly; Dick and Gretchen Roberts' kind and graciousness in providing such valuable service that I could not materially repay; The Francis family was like real family while I stayed in East Lansing, and Jana, my dear sister in the Lord, who encouraged me to press on; Equally encouraging was my family who, despite the distance, provided all kinds of support and love in the pursuit of this dream; Demetri, Marcelo, Rosanne, and Joe who helped countless times during the writing of the manuscript; and many others who in one way or another contributed toward the completion of this dissertation; Most of all to my Lord Jesus Christ and God the Father to whom this work is fully surrendered, and in the strength of His Spirit I completed this manuscript in victory. I am truly grateful to all. vii TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ........................................................................................................... xi LIST OF FIGURES ........................................................................................................ xiii KEY TO ABBREVIATIONS ........................................................................................ xiv CHAPTER 1 ..................................................................................................................... 1 INTRODUCTION ..................................................................................................... I Research Problem ............................................................................................... 4 Research Objectives ............................................................................................ 7 Organization of the Dissertation .......................................................................... 8 CHAPTER 2 ................................................................................................................... l 1 LITERATURE REVIEW ......................................................................................... 11 Developing the Accounting System .................................................................. l 1 Physical vs. Monetary Accounts ....................................................................... l7 Conceptual Framework and Structure of Accounting ........................................ 20 Measurement and Valuation Methods ............................................................... 23 Choice of Valuation Techniques ....................................................................... 24 Data Collection Techniques .............................................................................. 28 Sustainability and Local Resource Accounting ................................................. 30 CHAPTER 3 ................................................................................................................... 34 CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR NATURAL RESOURCE ACCOUNTING AT THE COMMUNITY LEVEL ............................................................................ 34 Conceptual Framework of the Rural Economy ................................................. 35 viii Community/Household Consumption and Production Decision Alternatives ...38 Natural Resource Accounts ............................................................................... 49 Measuring Sustainability of Natural Resources ................................................. 57 CHAPTER 4 ................................................................................................................... 6] DATA COLLECTION, ACCOUNTING STRUCTURE, AND LINKAGES TO RESOURCE SUSTAINABILITY ........................................................................... 61 Data Collection Processes ................................................................................. 61 Survey Process .................................................................................................. 62 The Survey Questionnaire ................................................................................. 66 Determining the Sample Size ............................................................................ 69 Developing the Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) Structure ............................ 74 Resources Sustainability and Community Well-being Interactions ................... 80 Secondary Sources of lnfonnation and Place of Study ...................................... 87 CHAPTER 5 ................................................................................................................... 89 RESULTS AND DISCUSSION ............................................................................... 89 Developing the Social Accounting Matrix ........................................................ 89 Uses of the SAM ............................................................................................. l 13 Sustainability of Natural Resources Recorded in the SAM ............................. 127 CHAPTER 6 ................................................................................................................. 137 SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS .......................... 137 Summary ......................................................................................................... 137 Conclusion ...................................................................................................... 144 Policy Implications ......................................................................................... 146 Limitations ...................................................................................................... 152 Recommendations for Future Studies .............................................................. 154 LITERATURE CITED ................................................................................................. 156 GLOSSARY ................................................................................................................. 166 APPENDIX A ............................................................................................................... 168 APPENDIX B ............................................................................................................... 176 APPENDIX C ............................................................................................................... 205 LIST OF TABLES Table 1. Study site and number of participants of focus group discussions in 5 communities. ..................................................................................................... 64 Table 2. Summary of households (HH) in the five communities covered by the Community-based Forest Management Program at the Bicol National Park. .................................................................................................................. 72 Table 3. Expansion factor and number of households (HH) —— in parenthesis — sampled by community and purok ..................................................................... 74 Table 4. SAM Production matrix (Sub-matrix A of the schematic diagram). .................. 96 Table 5. Destination of production outputs (Sub-matrix B of the schematic structure). .......................................................................................................... 99 Table 6. Other destinations of outputs of production activities (Sub-matrix C, D & E of the schematic structure) ........................................................................... 100 Table 7. Factors of production (Sub-matrix F of the schematic structure) ..................... 101 Table 8. Distribution of income from employing factors of production (Sub- matrix G of the schematic structure). .............................................................. 103 Table 9. Remittances, transfers and subsidies to (endogenous) institutions (Sub- matrix H, 1, J). ................................................................................................. 106 Table 10. Savings/Investment, natural capital depreciation and appreciation, and human capital (Sub-matrix K, L, M) ............................................................... 108 Table 11. Government, Rest of the world (ROW) or imports of input and consumption commodities (Sub-matrices N and P) ......................................... 1 11 Table 12. Government, Rest of the world (ROW) import of consumption commodities by institutions (Sub-matrices O, Q), and totals of expenditures. ................................................................................................... 1 1 1 Table 13. Proportion of various production activities to total production. ..................... 1 14 Table 14. Land ownership in the 20% sample and estimate for the five communities. ................................................................................................... 1 16 Table 15. Average propensities for expenditures on consumption for five communities .................................................................................................... 1 17 xi Table 16. Proportion of factors of production to total production .................................. 1 19 Table 17. Summary of endogenous, ME, and exogenous, GE, multipliers. .................... 122 Table 18. Change in production distribution resulting from external intervention. ....... 133 Table 19. Stand and stock table for CPEU, Inc. ............................................................ 202 Table 20. Stand and stock table for MUFFIN, Inc ......................................................... 203 Table 21. Stand and stock table for TIBKOI, Inc. ......................................................... 204 Table 22. Summary notations for endogenous and exogenous accounts of the SAM ................................................................................................................ 207 Table 23. Matrix of endogenous average propensities for expenditures. ....................... 208 Table 24. Matrix of MB of endogenous accounts and average propensities for exogenous accounts ......................................................................................... 211 Table 25. Livelihood activites of households in five communities. ............................... 215 Table 26. Total value of production activities of the 5 communities. ............................ 217 Table 27. Calculation of timber price (in Pesos) and proportion of cost components. .................................................................................................... 220 Table 28. Parameters used in simulation. ...................................................................... 223 Table 29. Simulation trials with varying area harvested and fire occurrences. .............. 225 Table 30. Simulation to determine the optimal level of harvest at varying fire occurrences. .................................................................................................... 226 Table 31. Summary of simulation run for opening and closing of stock of timber. ....... 227 xii LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1. Schematic diagram of the overall framework encompassing an account system at the community level. ......................................................................... 36 Figure 2. Structure of the community Social Accounting Matrix. ................................... 51 Figure 3. Simulation model for the stock and flow of natural resources (adopted from Repetto et a1., 1989 and DENR, 1991 ). .................................................... 59 Figure 4. The study communities are located on the eastern side of the Bicol National Park in the Bicol Region. .................................................................... 71 Figure 5. Components of the SAM and sources of information from survey questionnaire. .................................................................................................... 78 Figure 6. Schematic diagram of the SAM for five communities buffering the Bicol National Park. .......................................................................................... 91 Figure 7. Simulation of the effect of three harvest scenarios on natural resources stock. ............................................................................................................... 130 Figure 8. Trend of Opening and Closing Stock for three harvest options, and area disturbed. ........................................................................................................ 228 xiii KEY TO ABBREVIATIONS AWP - Annual Working Plan BNP - Bicol National Park C BF M, - Community-based forest management CGE - Computable General Equilibrium Model DENR - Department of Environment and Natural Resources ENRAP - Environment and Natural Resources Accounting Project FAO - Food and Agriculture Organization FDES - Framework for the Development of Environmental Statistics FGD - Focus Group Discussion FLUP - Forest Livelihood and Utilization Plan IRG - International Resources Group, Inc. LSMS - Living Standards Measurement Studies MVP - Marginal Value Product MEB - Material/Energy Balance MEW - Maximum Economic Welfare N1 - National Income NDP - Net Domestic Product NHE - New Household Economics NRA - Natural Resources Accounting NRMP - Natural Resource Management Program xiv OECD - Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development PNSCB - Philippine National Statistical Coordination Board SEEA - Satellite System for Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting SNA - System of National Accounts UN - United Nations UPLB - University of the Philippines Los Bar’los WB - World Bank WRI - World Resources Institutte XV CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION For several decades policy makers and economic planners have greatly relied on aggregate economic indices such as the Gross Domestic Product and National Income as indicators of a country's economic growth. The path to economic development has been viewed as an increasing rate of annual growth of these indices, following the trend of industrialized countries. Often, this path disregards effects on income distribution and quality of life both in the present and in the future. A closer examination of these indices, however, reveals inherent risks because the process of development depletes the environment and natural resources rapidly, possibly beyond recovery; yet depletion is not reflected in measures of growth. Thus, a variety of approaches have been developed recently in order to correct this deficiency (see Lutz and E1 Serafy, 1988; Abaza, 1992; Lutz, 1993; and Leefers and Castillo, 1998 for details of deficiency of these aggregate measures) and to derive genuine or sustainable income or growth indices, hopefully reflecting impacts on the environment and natural resources. Several approaches include physical measures or information as indicators on the state of the environment and natural resources. But interpreting voluminous physical information with different units of measure related to economic policy making is complex and subject to varied interpretations. A newer option is to link these physical indicators with economic indicators that are embodied in national accounts, thus essentially labeled the "greening of the account." This requires putting values on resources that are traditionally not valued in the market in order to be compatible with economic indicators. Planners are looking to revise such measures of growth as Gross Domestic Product, National Income and Depreciation so that they include indicators of resource sustainability (BEA, 1994). Revisions involve inclusion of depreciation or depletion of the environment and natural resources into the system of national accounts. Thus, the idea of "environment and natural resource accounting" was introduced as early as 19705 in accord with the concept of sustainable development. Since then, industrialized and developing countries have been developing concepts and methods of environmental and natural resource accounting. The biggest effort led to the addition in 1993 of the System of Environmental and Economic Accounts (SEEA), a satellite account instead of an integrated account, to the UN System of National Accounts (UN, 1993). SEEA is intended to be a standard for developing countries. Satellite accounts emphasizes the need to expand the analytical uses of the SNA for selected areas of concern such as environment and natural resources without disrupting the main function of the conventional or central account system. It provides for inclusion of additional information, additional concepts of valuation, cost and benefits of human economic activities, and linkages of physical data of the environmental and natural resources to the national accounts. Natural resource accounts were meant to provide clues and early warnings of exploitation of natural capital for economic production; excessive exploitation raises concerns about sustainability (Peskin, 1993). Theys (1989) identified at least four objectives of natural resource accounting: (1) to diagnose the current state of the environment; (2) to analyze the effects of environmental policies on economic performance and welfare; (3) to assess the value of resources that can be exploited for development; and (4) to identify possible options among the social, economic, and ecological objectives of development. Thus, these accounts provide vital information to economists and decision-makers for identifying areas of environmental and natural resource stress resulting from economic activities and assessing sustainability. Still, most natural resource accounting systems developed in industrialized and developing countries are national in scope. The approach, particularly in developing countries, concentrated on designing accounts for specific sectors such as forestry, mining and agriculture (including fisheries); they emphasized environmental quality effects more than the natural resources that are inputs for economic activities. JObstl and Hogg (1997) recognized that these trends are influenced by a variety of cultural, historical, political, legal, and economic factors. Most accounting efforts, however, neglected to incorporate two important components: household production (see Becker, 1965 for definition) and rural economic activities. It was reasonable previously to accept these deficiencies, but the role of household production and consumption was increasing (Ruddel and Rodinelli, 1983). James (1996) cited the estimate by Hawrylyshyn (1976) that household production was typically one-third the size of GNP on average. By factoring unmarketed household production into national accounts, the International Resource Group et a1. (1996) argued that the forestry sector aggregate account potentially increases by 30 percent. Thus, if household activities related to use of natural resources was ignored, the gross domestic product (GDP) would be biased. Research Problem Of particular importance are economic transactions of households in rural areas that occur outside organized markets, particularly in developing countries such as the Philippines. For instance, household-bound goods (production outputs directly consumed by households) are neither transacted in the market nor involve monetary transactions, and thus are not included in the calculation of aggregate national accounts. The national account system does not include these goods; thus, aggregate estimates of depreciation or appreciation at the national level can only be considered partial and incomplete. Accounts do not reflect real appreciation or depreciation of natural resources. Therefore, there is a need to incorporate accounts from rural household economic activities. By including these activities, national accounts can become more reflective and useful for policy and decision-making pertaining to sustainability of natural resources. Household production activities for own-consumption are particularly large in communities subsisting or alternatively depending on forest resources. During the late 19805 it was estimated that 20% of the Philippine population lived in the mostly forested highlands, commonly referred to as uplands. Subsistence activities in these upland rural communities are more than those recorded in national accounts. Population increases potentially increased the use of non-timber resources, notably fuelwood. Further use increases may occur due to the government policy that delegated management of public forests to communities adjacent to or within these forests. These communities need to develop tools for effective management of forest resources. Decision-making at the local level needs simple and vital sets of information that will help them come up with rational decisions in terms of efficiency, equity and sustainability of forest resources. Thus far, efforts to develop accounting frameworks for rural economic activities that include natural resources exploitation are limited. Other than the long process it takes for accounts development, support for such work is minimal due to the current national- level emphasis. More so, natural resource accounting is a relatively new field; it became popular only with the advent of environmentalism. Such accounting endeavors have not been popular among many policy makers and international organizations, because they represent a more conservative "status quo" approach to economic growth. It is likely that the framework and structure of the accounting system at the local level will be different from those at the national level, depending on the economic structure at the community (Taylor and Adelman, 1996). A number of other factors may influence development of accounts at the village level; several influencing factors that are relevant to this study are mentioned here: 0 stakeholders’ (within and outside the community) and community preferences and their household characteristics influence what activities and elements need to be included in the accounts; 0 analysts' and decision-makers' degree of concern for substantive economic, ecological and social issues may define components of accounts; 0 issues on tenure and property rights (i.e. community-based forest management), participation in management, and decision-making process define the structure of the accounting system; 0 governance of the common property resources complicates analysis of resource sustainability; and o valuation methods used in account systems limit types of non-market goods that can be included in the accounts. All these issues potentially influence accounting frameworks at the community or village level. The main focus therefore is an accounting framework that will be useful for local and national decision-making in order to assess sustainability of resources. But linkages with the national level must be considered. At this stage the focus is on renewable resources in forest-dependent communities, and thus on natural resources as capital for economic production. Environmental concerns though important are beyond the scope of this study. Other than usefulness for local decision-making, recent international developments on forestry emphasized the need for sustainable forest management. Examples include developing criteria and indicators for forest sustainability and "green certification" of forest products that aim to provide consumers with information on how forests are being managed (Bratkovich, undated; Kiekens, 1999). Forest certification and auditing are "emerging trends" in business transactions on products coming from natural resources. Therefore, in order to be competitive in international trade, community forests must initiate efforts toward sustainable management and having their forest certified. Natural resource accounting and these other new mechanisms ensure that forests are sustainably managed. These are notable concerns that policy makers at the national level will need to address. Research Objectives In view of the above issues, two main questions are addressed in this study: Can an accounting system be workable at the local level and at the same time provide useful information for national level decision-making? And, can the accounts provide indicators of sustainability of the forest management system? Other basic questions to ask are “What needs to be measured (including values) at the community level?" "How are these measured?" "What tools are helpful in developing measures?" All these questions are helpful guides in conceptualizing a framework for decision-making at all levels. In the light of the above, the overall purpose of the research is to develop natural resource accounting and resource valuation framework for forest-based communities in the Philippines in order to assess resource sustainability under varying management regimes. Included in framework development is the link of human production activities and consumption on the stock and flow of natural resources. Specific objectives are: (1) To develop a physical and monetary accounting framework that captures community forest resources including those not accounted for at the national scale (i.e., natural resource accounting), (2) To link the accounting framework with household and community forest production options (flows) and capital (timber) stocks (i.e., sustainability). Organization of the Dissertation Chapter 2, Literature Review, examines various account systems for environmental and natural resources that relate to framework development at the community level. The review covers how account systems and their components are identified, the choice of physical and monetary approaches, valuation methods and measurement. The usefulness of accounts for assessing sustainability of forest as capital in economic production is also presented. Chapter 3, Conceptual Framework for Natural Resource Accounting at the Community Level, presents a conceptual natural resource accounting framework for rural community forest management using a concept of achieving well-being of household through satisfaction of consumption needs. The chapter includes conceptual procedures and techniques for measuring and valuing consumption and production activities and for assessing sustainability of natural resources. Chapter 4, Data Collection, Analysis Methods and the Accounting Structure, discusses the field procedure of data collection through surveys (i.e. face-to-face interview) and focus group discussions. The chapter includes synthesis of survey data obtained during the 1998 community survey, description of study areas, and summaries of demographic characteristics of households. It is important to highlight the institutional context in rural areas where the study was conducted. Institutional context as defined by Appendini et a1. (1999) refers to "dynamic institutional arragements which influence their access to different resources and services which are essential for their income generating strategies." The site in which this study was conducted was under a community-based forest management agreement between five communities and the government. The forest that these five communities encompass is a second growth forest that the government refers to as a "buffer forest." Chapter 5, Results and Discussion, presents analysis of survey results, the structure of community-level accounts, and a simulation model for assessing resource sustainability. Major findings, strengths and weaknesses of the framework, and how this framework can be used for local-level decision-making are included. Linkages to national accounts are also noted. In chapter 6, Summary, Conclusions and Policy Recommendations, several additional issues on natural resource accounting are discussed. Among them are politics of community forestry that affect accounting of resources, deforestation and associated land-use changes, small-scale timber harvesting, valuation of non-market resources, adjustment of national income for household consumption of non-market forest products, and estimation of the value and sustainability of forest products which are consumed directly by households. Also, policy recommendations and suggested areas of change and refinement of the framework for future work on institutionalizing accounts system are presented. 10 CHAPTER 2 LITERATURE REVIEW This study develops an accounting framework applicable at the village level for management of community forests. The previous chapter noted the importance of household consumption and production activities in rural areas. A system of accounts for assessing the impact of rural economic activities on natural resources, therefore, must encompass household activities. This chapter reviews various account frameworks, techniques of valuation and sustainability assessment, and their usefulness for developing natural resource accounts at the community or village level. Developing the Accounting System The review of various accounting models developed in both industrialized and developing countries provides direction on what system would apply to the community, with an emphasis on household consumption and production. Criteria used in reviewing these models include: 0 ability to capture local economic conditions (i.e., households as consumption and production centers), 11 0 usability for evaluation, monitoring and decision-making (e.g., whether to apply purely physical or physical with monetary accounting). and 0 simplicity of structure and distinct boundary of the accounts (i.e., whether it can be used by local decision-makers that include households, community leaders and local government units). The discussion that follows explores various frameworks and structures of account systems in the context of rural communities. This provides a foundation for designing a relevant account system. General Approaches to Natural Resource A ccounting Literature abounds with conceptual frameworks that attempt to incorporate (or capture) environmental and natural resources into the system of national accounts with the aim of revising measures of economic growth. However, they inadequately cover economic activities of households in rural areas. Commonly cited frameworks include the UN System of Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting (SEEA), Peskin's Environment and Natural Resources Framework, Repetto's Accounting for Natural Resources Depreciation, Nordhaus and Tobin's Maximum Economic Welfare (MEW) framework developed for Japan, the French Patrimony Accounts, and the Framework for Development of Environmental Statistics (FDES) (Peskin, 1993; Vincent, 1997; UN, 1993). These account systems, applied to both industrialized and developing countries oflen include sectoral accounts such as forestry. mining, and agriculture aggregated at the 12 national scale (see example ofCosta Rica, Solorzano et al., 1991). Other accounts focus on a landscape scale such as for watersheds and ecosystems (Xu et al., 1995; King et al., 1995). Thus, there is a need to develop an account system for rural household economic activities that can be included in national accounts. Harrison (1993) looked at development of account systems in stages by categorizing accounting approaches into stages of development. The first stage was the accounting of environmental and natural resources based on the material-energy balance (MEB) concept, where environmental information is expressed in physical terms using an input-output structure. The second stage involves converting physical environmental information into stocks and flows called natural resource accounts (NRA), which are primarily physical but can be enhanced to include monetary accounts. The SEEA (a satellite system for the SNA) is the model for both physical and monetary accounts. because it contains stock and flow information. The third stage is transforming natural resource accounts from physical to monetary terms. thus, resembling the SNA. Usability for decision and policy making is an important factor in developing the accounts, whether at the local or national level. The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD, 1995) classifies most account systems into three levels of use: macro, sectoral, and micro levels. The macro level accounts are used mainly to adjust and calculate alternative national accounts aggregates, in order to reflect the depletion of natural resources and degradation of the environment to improve aggregate measures of general welfare. The sectoral accounts focus on more narrowly l3 defined field of application to particular environmental media and natural resources such as forests, water or energy, obviously for central planning and management-related purposes. The micro accounts focused more on the firm level because the pressure for green consumerism motivates firms to conduct environmental audits and certification (OECD, 1995). However, literature on micro-level accounting that includes environmental and natural resources are rather rare. Other landscape-level approaches, such as the watershed management unit or an ecosystem, are proposed obviously for management purposes (Xu et al., 1995). Thus, macro- and sectoral-level frameworks are more common than micro—level or localized frameworks because of the drive to revise national aggregate measures of growth. Peskin (1993) categorized most macro-level account frameworks into four general approaches. First, accounting of environmental activities that are already reflected in conventional accounts such as assembly of pollution control expenditures (Statistics Canada, 1997) — those effects that are simply a result of all economic activities. Second, physical accounting of environmental and natural resources activities that are related to economic activities, such as pollution discharges by sector and stocks/flows of natural resources. Third, accounting for depreciation of renewable and non-renewable resources in order to adjust income estimates (e. g. NDP). Two examples of which are the Repetto approach for 1ndonesia(Repetto et a1, 1989) and the Nordhaus-Tobin Measure of Economic Welfare (MEW) for Japan (Perman et al., 1996). Fourth, and the most ambitious, is a comprehensive accounting system — both physical and monetary - to expand the coverage of the conventional accounts in order to include environmental and 14 natural resources. The French system (Peskin and Lutz, 1993), the Peskin accounting system for the Chesapeake Bay (Grambsch et al., 1993), and the UN SEEA (UN, 1993) are examples of this fourth approach. Sectoral accounts such as agriculture, forestry, mining and related industries are commonly developed in tandem with macro accounts by industrialized countries (Peskin and Lutz, 1990; BEA, 1994; BEA, 2000; BEA, 2000 ). Developing countries such as Indonesia, Mexico, Papua New Guinea, and the Philippines followed suit (WRI, 1991; DENR et al., 1996; Leefers and Castillo, 1998; Vincent, 1998). These were intended to monitor impacts of economic policies on resources, that is, to measure impacts of environmental regulations, emissions taxes, and pollution (Atkinson et al., 1997). A number of studies demonstrate that local environmental and natural resource accounts incorporated into the SNA may significantly change the picture of national accounts (Friend, 1993; Hecht and Peskin, 1993; UN, 1993). Peskin et a1. (1992) proposed a framework to include fuelwood consumption by the household sector into the national accounts using cases in Africa. The UN SEEA, on the other hand. proposed to incorporate household production via a satellite system (UN, 1993). In the Philippines, the Environmental and Natural Resource Accounting Project (ENRAP) project estimated this sector which proved to have a significant influence on GDP (DENR, 1991). However, community-level accounting studies that include household activities are scant in literature, because of equally scant support for such efforts. A lone study by Saxena and Agarwal (1997) developed accounts system for tree growers in India, but confined 15 their work in timber resources to fuelwood. The inadequacy of local-level accounting emphasized the need to extend the coverage of national accounts to include non-market activities in rural economies, particularly those that are household-bound (Hecht and Peskin, 1993). Most account developers aim for simplicity of structure. However, developing accounts for economic transactions alone, that include non-market goods and services, proved to be complex (Peskin, 1993; UN, 1993; Vincent, 1998) and required considerable survey and data collection efforts. Some countries approached this incrementally by confining assessments to a limited number of important environmental media and natural resources (i.e., water, energy, sub-soil assets, or forests). Still these efforts faced difficult challenges in valuation (Hecht and Peskin, 1993; OEC D, 1995; Darmstadter, 2000). These difficulties were reasons that no natural resources, specifically those that have no known or acceptable markets or monetary value, are integrated into the system of national accounts. Instead they are appended as satellite accounts (UN, 1993) or as augmented accounts mordhaus and Kokkelenberg, 1999). Satellite accounts imply that core national income and product accounts remains to reflect mainly market activities, but renewable and environmental resources serve as supplemental accounts to provide materials for policy makers. Augmented accounts on the other hand imply extending the national and income accounts to include natural resources and the environment, but not integrated into the core accounts. 16 These challenges suggest that accounting systems at the community level should focus incrementally first on economic-production activities, as well as the provision of adequate information for rational decisions by community planners. Decisions regarding exploitation of resources must be done rationally in the pursuit of sustainability, at the local level, since current community residents are not the only stakeholders of the forest. Atkinson et a1. (1997) suggested an alternative way of developing environmental and natural resource accounts using the social accounting matrix (SAM) structure for localized socioeconomic impact analysis. Its suitability for natural resource accounts lies in its usefulness for policy analysis — being a flexible framework. Taylor and Adelman (1996) reported work done on developing a village-level social accounting matrix that focused on agricultural commodities. They compared the usefulness of the social accounting matrix with the computable general equilibrium model (CGE) for defining a village economy. Taylor and Adelman (1996) specifically recommended use of the SAM for defining the structure of the village economy, but suggested use of CGE for defining equilibrium conditions. Physical vs. Monetary Accounts Units of measure in accounts considerably affect the usefulness of accounting information for policy analysis. Accounting approaches range from purely physical to monetary or from purely ecological to economic, but physical accounts are basic features of all systems. The foundational framework for these systems is the material/energy 17 balance (MEB) concept, developed in the late 19605 and early 19705 by Ayers and Kneese (1969). The Framework for the Development of Environmental Statistics (FDES) developed by the UN Statistical Office (Rapport and Friend, 1979; UN 1991; Friend, 1993) emphasized physical accounting as input for developing natural resource accounts. The more complex French environmental accounting system was conceived to assess the interaction between economic, ecological and social environments, but it was developed from a quantitative and qualitative account of the environment (Peskin and Lutz, 1990). Both recognized the necessity of developing an environmental information system in physical terms before developing an economic system of accounts for the environment and natural resources can be developed — the approach for most systems developed by industrialized countries. Physical accounts are necessary but not sufficient for understanding economic relationships. To illustrate, Statistics Canada (1997) used the example of mineral accounts where aggregating tons of gold and silver (similar to the water-diamond paradox) would be less helpful for policy analysis purposes. The resulting aggregation will be meaningless considering that they are valued differently (Statistics Canada, 1997). Therefore, aggregate monetary accounting systems for environmental and natural resources face the dual challenge of transforming diverse physical information into a common unit of measure by assigning values to them and of remaining useful for policy analysis. 18 Some proponents of monetary accounting suggest use of a "numeraire" by using money value (Hueting et al., 1993). In order to accomplish this, weights and ratio to market commodities (Statistics Canada, 1997) for environmental services are recommended, and thus converting them to monetary accounts. However, meaningful interpretation for policy is still the main issue. Other authors recommended that natural resource accounting as simply physical accounting because of these conceptual and empirical challenges (UN, 1993; Vincent, 1998). Otherwise, simple satellite accounts to complement the monetary system of national accounts are recommended (UN, 1993). Peskin (1998), however, proposed to integrate depreciation of the environment and natural resource in the SNA, with a distinction made between physical and economic depreciation. Thus, the satellite approach came about because some experts rejected the idea of making substantial changes in the conventional SNA (UN, 1993). The latter is used for other types of analysis, requiring monetary valuations such as short-term monetary and fiscal policies, that cannot be consistently done for all environmental services. The UN SEEA became a model of physical and monetary accounts, but as a satellite system to the SNA (UN, 1993). It was intended to describe the environmental-economic relations, monitor environmental changes caused by economic activities, and be useful in assessing environmental costs and benefits (Bartelmus et al., 1993). Hence, monetary accounts including the environment and natural resources have much room for research. Linking those physical data to monetary values are steps that 19 need to be undertaken in order to link NRA to the SNA (UN, 1991) and to be useful for economic policy analysis and decision-making. Most international bodies recommended the idea of localized accounting to pilot test monetary accounts (UN, 1993; Peskin, 1993). Conceptual Framework and Structure of Accounting The structure of the account system at the community or village level must be useful for their needs. Theys (1994) suggested that perceived economic need influences the structure of accounts created. Therefore, a prerequisite to developing an account structure for the community is understanding the concept of rural well-being and its link to natural resources via their production activities. This requires careful modeling of community/village economic activities, specifically consumption and production as they relate to resource exploitation. The household is the basic unit of economic activity in rural areas that functions as production and consumption center (Taylor and Adelman, 1996; Becker, 1965). Becker (1965) first modeled economics of household production and consumption activities, and became the foundation of New Home Economics (NHE). In the rural context, household well-being is conceptualized as maximizing consumption from production outputs from farm, natural resources exploitation, and employment. According to Ruddel and Rodinelli (1983). production activities of most 20 households in rural areas consisted of several complementary activities, the most common of which were small-scale farming, fishing, animal husbandry, and collecting forest products. Households also interact with institutions outside of the village, and thus were important factors that define the rural economy. These activities and linkages influenced land-use (Cervigni, 1998), and thus affected the condition of natural resources under the control of the village. Cervigni (1998) developed a computer-based model to predict the impact of these linkages on the stocks of secondary forests, agricultural and pasture lands in a village in Mexico. Endogenous variables of the model — that proved to influence human alteration of the environment —included farmers' objectives, opportunities for land use, land tenure policies, available technology, opportunities for salaried work outside the village, and government policies. Taylor and Adelman (1996) chose to apply the social accounting matrix (SAM) and the computable general equilibrium (CGE) model because of these inter-linkages among production activities and institutions within or outside the village. Hence, the SAM fits into the community/village-level economic structure for assessing impacts of rural policy. Framers of the UN SNA support the idea that SAM provides a flexible framework for socioeconomic analysis (UN, 1993). Atkinson et al. (1997) pointed out the usefulness of SAM for the linkages between the environment and the economy. The SAM is a type of an input-output matrix. The more common applications of input-output matrix similar to SAM were on national level in order to assess impact of 21 certain sectors on a nation's economy (Miller and Blair, 1985). However, interests at the regional and community level economy have increased, particularly in the Philippines where local autonomy was emphasized. This has led to modifications of the input-output matrix in order to reflect peculiar characteristics. One notable difference was in the classification of account elements: in traditional input-output matrix, institutions or final consumers are treated as exogenous, while in village SAM certain institutions are treated as endogenous. The SAM has become a common tool useful for village economy assessment, particularly for developing countries (Taylor and Adelman, 1996). The components of the SAM are structured by institutions (i.e., households, government, firms etc.), and the SAM is acknowledged to be flexible for any type of socioeconomic assessment (UN, 1993). A SAM can incorporate renewable resources as capital. Details on the origin and evolution of SAM can be traced to the work by Pyatt and Round (1977). This work further evolved with application to measurement of sustainability by Atkinson et al. (1997) and application to assessing a village economy by Taylor and Adelman (1996). As a companion to the SAM, balance sheets that combine yearly opening and closing stocks of resources are recommended for renewable resources assessment (Repetto et al., 1989; delos Angeles, 1991; Peskin, 1993; UN, 1993; UN, 1993; Atkinson et a1, 1997; Statistics Canada, 1997). Between these two stock records are factors that affect opening and closing stock such as harvest, damages and changes in values of stocks. The frequency and intensity of these changes, induced by human exploitation 22 determines the opening and closing stocks of each year. This type of account presentation and its link to consumption and production serves to evaluate the sustainability of resources. Hartwick (1990) and Maler (1991) provided theoretical background for evaluating the Optimal path of resource utilization for renewable and non-renewable resources over time, while Vincent (1998) developed the theoretical particulars for forest resources as they related to resource accounting. These theoretical discussions are the foundations to developing physical and monetary account structure that include consumption, production and stock and flow of resources. The next section presents literature on measurement and valuation of accounts. Measurement and Valuation Methods Incorporating rural household activities into the account system requires use of a common measure comparable with commodities already transacted in the market. Therefore, an essential undertaking in developing accounting systems that involve natural resources is to put all entries into the account using the same measure. Thus, one aspect of account system development was to develop measurement and valuation methods applicable to marketed and non-market-transacted goods; particularly those directly consumed by households in rural settings. These two concepts, measurement and valuation, prove to be essential and inseparable for this and other natural resources accounting studies. 23 Ideally, under a competitive situation (assumed Pareto-efficient markets), accounting of market transactions would suffice to reflect these natural resources exploitation activities. However, most rural communities in developing countries are not fully integrated into the exchange economy (Taylor and Adelman, 1996). These rural communities are largely subsistence-agriculture-based where households directly consume part or most of their production outputs. Thus, a considerable portion of their production is not reflected in the market. Hence, market values for most of these household outputs, Perman et al. (1996) pointed out, do not necessarily exist and thus should be obtained in some other way. It is important to emphasize that the focus of valuation is on commodities and not on ecosystem functions of natural resources. For examples on forest ecosystem functions, Barbier (1994) summarized a number of valuation methods. The next sections reviewed literature on valuation techniques. Choice of Valuation Techniques A number of theoretical and empirical studies helped define suitable valuation methods for non-marketed goods. Schweitzer (1991), Miller (1991), and Peskin (1992) provided overviews of valuation concepts as they relate to accounting. Several authors (Maler, 1992; Shaw, 1992; Barbier, 1994; Perman et al. 1996; Bann, 1998) explored conceptual methods of valuation, and suggested methods of collecting this information. 24 Hufschmidt et a1. (1983) classified valuation techniques into three categories: (1) use of direct market value, (2) use of market value of substitute (surrogate) or complementary goods, and (3) use of survey techniques to elicit valuation. The first two categories make use of the market price, while the third is based on a contingent market. Market prices, Bann (1998) noted, tend to underestimate true economic value because they do not account for consumer surplus. Market price also requires adjustment for any market or policy failure to reflect opportunity cost to society; the resulting value is the shadow price of the resource used. The third category is based on willingness-to-pay by an economic agent, a non-market valuation approach, where a hypothetical market is created. The choice of which technique to use is dictated by what analysts will need. In the context of incorporating rural economic activities into national accounts, market price is most appropriate, because it provides methodological consistency with existing accounts. The third category implies a total economic value composed of potential market price and consumer surplus, which is not comparable with market values in conventional accounts. Hence, valuation techniques applicable for this study are confined to market valuation. Bann (1998) listed six categories of market-based valuation techniques in literature with accompanying examples: 0 market value - market prices, efficiency prices; 0 related goods approach - barter exchange approach, direct substitute approach, and indirect substitution approach; 25 0 cost-based evaluation - (indirect) opportunity cost approach, restoration cost, replacement cost, relocation cost, and preventive expenditure, 0 indirect valuation techniques - travel cost method, hedonic pricing method, labor market approach, and market value of physical effects (the latter example include dose-response, damage functions, production function approach, human capital); and 0 benefits transfer - using data generated from a study site to estimate values in another site. Many published studies illustrate usage of these techniques specifically applied to village settings. Saxena and Agrawal (1997) used market value of commodities in an attempt to augment the financial accounts of a tree-growers' cooperative in India, and in order to include social, economic and environmental values. The SEEA employed a simple approach using cost data where the value of natural assets is the cost that is necessary to keep the natural capital intact (Bartelmus et al., 1993). Both Miller (1990) and Schweitzer (1992) favor use of indirect valuation based on productivity change over direct methods (such as those listed above) for developing countries. Such preferences are quite understandable because most environment and natural resource problems in developing countries pertain to use (Vincent, Crawford and Hoehn, 1990). A number of studies focused on opportunity cost valuation. James (1996) used "time used" and market price of household activity to compare the opportunity cost and market price valuation methods for household production. For non-timber forest 26 commodities, Vincent (1998) proposed that the total value of household consumption of non-timber forest products is proportional to the opportunity cost of labor used in collecting these products: the wage rate times labor inputs. However, Vincent qualified that this proportionality holds only when forest earns no rent: that is, forest access is not restricted. Otherwise, the consumption value of timber is larger than the opportunity cost of labor. For other components of the forest, Vincent used shadow price defined as the value of the next best alternative use of the commodity (Vincent, 1998). Opportunity cost (based on time-use) approaches do not necessarily apply for valuing all commodities. In some cases, opportunity cost approach is useful for production of goods for own consumption; such as in subsistence agriculture that has no market transactions (Peskin, 1995; and Vincent, 1998). As an example, for non-timber forest products, the total value of household consumption is considered proportional to the opportunity cost of labor used in collecting these products. However, the resulting value can only be exactly equal to the opportunity cost if the following conditions hold: (1) rent of the forest product is zero, (2) no excess capacity in production, and (3) no underemployment and free access to resources. If these conditions are not present the opportunity cost will not to equal market value (Peskin, 1995). Rural economic systems, in particular, are not characterized by these conditions. Hence, despite its shortcomings market prices are commonly used because they are observable. The above samples of usage of valuation techniques provided a picture of the range of possible techniques applicable. The cost of data collection, purpose of study, and time involved determine what can be measured and valued, as well as the choice of 27 valuation techniques. Hence, this study covers only valuation of conventional goods or commodities using market values — for non-marketed commodities. Further, valuation method that will apply to household consumption and production depend on market transactions by households. It is important to note that valuation difficulties arise for forest goods (and services) that involve variety of uses. F uelwood is one case that has both marketed and non-market features. F uelwood collected for household consumption in rural areas does not go through normal market channels (Peskin et al., 1993), and does not fully substitute as energy source; hence, its value would not be comparable to alternative marketed sources of energy. For instance, a ton of fuelwood will not have the same value as a ton of liquefied petroleum gas. This serves to illustrate the potential variations of interpretation of valuation results. Data Collection Techniques Data collection instruments must be parsimonious, yet cover goods not transacted in the market that require monetary measures in order to be comparable with marketed goods. Grootaert (1982) recommended that data sources for evaluating household well- being are standard household-level surveys that focus on measuring their welfare, while economic activities of households are based on budget surveys (Taylor and Adelman, I996). Ruddel and Rodinelli (1983), however, argued that surveys, though useful for piecemeal studies, may have little value for evaluating resource systems because they do 28 not incorporate complementary household activities and functions such as those listed in the previous section. Thus, the need for complementary survey such as focus group discussions and interviews are implied. The method of data collection adopted should be useful for those who will be using the account system. Therefore the types of value that are important, what is readily available at affordable cost, and ease of handling and analysis are important considerations in data collection (Bann, 1998). Three useful studies adequately covered data collection instruments helpful for this study. The Living Standard Measurement Studies (LSMS) of the World Bank used three different levels of survey instruments to assess welfare of households: household survey. community survey, and market survey — where price of vendors are surveyed (Grosh and Glewwe, 1995). Grosh and Glewwe (1995) explained component modules of these surveys. For time use data, Acharya (1982) recommended the use of recall, observation and diary keeping, details of which are explained in World Bank LSMS Working Paper no. 18. Finally, Taylor and Adelman (1996) used budget surveys to estimate a village social accounting matrix where households were asked about types of production, the uses of outputs, inputs used whether purchased and non-purchased. and their input prices. Therefore, the data for the study will involve household surveys and community questionnaire in the form of focus group discussion, and secondary data on inventory of resources. These procedures are likely to encounter a number of difficulties such as data availability for stock of community resources, ability of respondents to recall information 29 about consumption and production activities. and precision of response depending on the rigidity of the questionnaire. Grootaert (1982) offered a number of suggestions for capturing data in these situations. The ideal is a compact survey that can capture the multi-dimensional requirements (production, consumption, demographics, environmental concerns) of the study. Dividing the survey into modules, prioritizing information needs, making use of screening questions (Grosh and Glewwe, 1995) and reducing the size of questionnaire by asking questions at the community level are very helpful recommendations (Grootaert, 1982). To that end, focus group discussions are a helpful tool for compacting household surveys, and the budget surveys format adopted by Taylor and Adelman (1996) are particularly useful in view of developing the social account matrix. Grosh and Glewwe (1995) described the data management procedures for survey data. These are important considerations in design of survey and data collection. Sustainability and Local Resource Accounting Exploitation of natural resources is the main issue in community forestry; hence, the question of sustainability naturally arises. Many dimensions emerged from discussions on sustainability that have relevance in defining local resource accounting. At the local level, the issue of what to sustain seems easy because these are normally tied to costs and benefits of local stakeholders (Saxena and Agrawal, 1997). However. at a higher level of decision making such as regional. national or global levels, this becomes 30 more difficult due to linkages between levels and complexity associated with broader systems. Toman (1999) pointed out that at present, there is no consensus about what constituted sustainability and that such a consensus may be long in the future. Literature on this subject alone involved voluminous discussions on sustainability or sustainable development (Pezzey, 1992). It covered issues such as intergenerational equity and how to deal with uncertainty of preferences. Should analysts consider a finite or an infinite number of generations? What is the safe minimum standard? How can the level of resiliency of environmental systems be determined? There are arguments on whether to adopt strong or weak sustainability as related to substitutability of natural capital to man- made capital. Some would prefer to treat sustainability as a constraint in maximizing well-being or utility. There are also various issues on reliability of measures of sustainability and irreversibility; questions on insufficiency of traditional economic criteria of cost-benefit analysis, and discounting. The ultimate objective of all these discussions is to define policy prescriptions that will promote sustainability of resources. Pezzey (1992) believed that arriving at a mathematical solution to complex sustainability issues is insurmountable. In order to minimize complexity of their models, most modelers ignore environmental amenities in determining sustainable economic growth (Pezzey, 1992). Instead, the focus is on maximizing consumption that best sustains well-being of present and future generations (Pezzey, 1992; Beckennan, 1994). A simple conceptual formulation presented by Pezzey (1992) maximizes U=U (C ), typical 31 of most dynamic optimization models. In the traditional economic utilitarian approach, maximizing consumption over a time horizon subject to certain constraints sets the optimal path of growth. This maximization over time suggests introducing a utility discount rate, or the rate at which future utility is discounted to be comparable with the present utility levels. Atkinson et al., (1997) suggested (based on Solow) that a constant consumption path can be achieved by setting the discount rate equal to the marginal product of capital. In practical terms, the marginal product of capital should be equal to the growth rate or marginal productivity of the resource base. Those who propose a common numeraire for better interpretation suggested translating these productivity measures in monetary terms. Once translated, these changes in real value of assets (that is, the change in volume times a constant price) should not be negative. Optimal control theory proved helpful in conceptualizing sustainability of resources. However, Pezzey (1992) argued that optimal control models that deal with renewable and non-renewable resources have intrinsic problems, particularly those that deal with more than two endogenous variables. Hence, most modelers resort to partial equilibrium and deal only with a single resource or system of resource (e. g. fisheries or forestry). The alternative to such difficulty is simulation modeling based on real data and pre-defined functional forms. This approach takes into consideration various phenomena and tests several assumptions, singly or even for multiple cases. Various tools applicable for these kinds of evaluation include structural path analysis (Defoumy and Thorbecke. 1984), computable general equilibrium model (Taylor and Adelman, 1996), and process network theory applied by Alocilja et al., (Saama et al., 1990; Alocilja, 1990) for a study 32 on dairy cattle. All three approaches need intensive modeling and data, hence, simple simulation models that isolate the resource in question such as timber resources suffices for this study. In summary, this chapter surveyed literature to cover three important goals of this study. First, the survey of accounting frameworks developed in industrialized and developing countries suggests developing a localized and flexible framework with the ability for incremental development. Account frameworks focused initially on household economic transactions, but with potential to include intangible uses in the future. The SAM should adequately capture village level economic activity and hence, be a useful structure for localized appraisal and decision-making needs. Thus, valuation of ecosystem services is relegated to future studies. Second, measurement and valuation of outputs of consumption and production activities should be compatible with accounting needs hence, the need to focus on market valuation. Valuation techniques dictate the data collection method employed. Third, assessing sustainability of household consumption and production activities and their impact on stock and flow of natural resources suggest use of simulation modeling but confined or limit this modeling to a limited number of resources. The next chapter develops the conceptual framework of local accounting system capturing the results of this review. 33 CHAPTER 3 CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK FOR NATURAL RESOURCE ACCOUNTING AT THE COMMUNITY LEVEL The previous chapter explored literature in order to define an accounting framework applicable at the community/village level and useful for decision-making. This chapter develops the conceptual framework for the accounting system, as a basis for the empirical study presented in the next chapter. Development required defining the broader framework that covers linkages between economic agents and their impact on natural resources. Natural resource accounting, in the structure of the social accounting matrix (SAM), becomes the information system for these interactions. The SAM captures the state of the economy of one period, and provides indicators of the demand for natural resources. Two important processes covered by this broader framework are the community/household economic activities and natural resources processes. Therefore, two accompanying conceptual models supplement the SAM for analysts and decision- makers: a model of household/community production decisions as affected by internal and external interventions and a model of natural resources sustainability. Thus, the SAM, the principal focus of this research, is only one component of a broader model that integrates natural resources. The first section emphasizes the need to define the economic structure and linkages in the community/village. This economic model incorporates internal and 34 external factors affecting household/community consumption and production decisions. The second section further discusses details of the household/community production decisions. A simple mathematical expression defines household consumption and production decisions, and serves as a basis for identifying elements of the accounts. The model also captures impacts of exogenous factors/interventions on economic activities in the community. These interventions come in the form of policy/decision options for sustaining productivity of timber resources. The third section outlines the Social accounting matrix that incorporates both marketed and non-marketed transactions of households and the community. The fourth section describes the conceptual framework for simulating timber resources stock and flow as affected by community economic activities recorded in the SAM. All three component frameworks of the broader rural economic framework interact dynamically over time, though the SAM is treated as static here. Conceptual Framework of the Rural Economy The natural resource accounts framework development begins with an overall understanding of rural community economics and household well-being in the context of rural agriculture. Interactions of households, mostly through consumption and production activities, with domestic and external factors define community/village economic activities. Endogenous household characteristics and exogenous factors such as institutions, government, and market forces dynamically influence consumption patterns and production activities. Household consumption patterns and production activities in turn affect the stock and flow of natural resources. By tracing these linkages and 35 outcomes of resources stock and flow, analysts identify various policy and decision- making options in order to sustain natural resources productivity. Therefore, the three major components of the overall accounting framework include (1) the SAM, the accounting framework, that portrays the community economy, (2) a natural resource sustainability model in the form of simulation, and (3) the community/household production (economic) decision model. Figure 1 shows the schematic relationships of these three components. The next sections discuss these component frameworks in turn. Community/Household Consumption and Production Decision Exogenous Factors _, Endogenous Factors , Household Characteristics Local Communrty " Demographics (size, composition, etc.) and External L . . - abor Institutions -> -Preferences -Assets/ Property Government Policies "> — Agricultural land 0Land tenure — Common property (forest ) °Production levels -' — Movable assets -Pricing/Wages -Fiscal/Monetary _’ . T , j . Well-being = U(Consumptron) Production/Income Altematrves -> -Food, clothing, shelter 0 -Agricultural farm production Market FOTCCS -Outputs of production -Forest exploitation -> oMarket purchases -Other non-land—based livelihood 9 i Natural Resources Accounts (SAM) -Marketed and non-marketed -Consumption indicators - Production indicators - Natural resources indicators —Depreciation/Appreciation —Stock of natural resources Natural Resources (Timber) Sustainability Information -Opening and closing stock I ~Harvest -Sustainabi1ity indicators -Policy/Decision options Figure 1. Schematic diagram of the overall framework encompassing an account system at the community level. 36 The C ommunity/Household Consumption and Production Decision Model describes interactions or linkages of exogenous and endogenous factors that influence consumption patterns and production decisions: - Household demographics, preferences. assets or properties such as agricultural land, housing, and movable assets influence household decisions on consumption and production activities; - Community institutions, market forces, and government policies either constrain or promote consumption and production choices; - Consumption patterns determine the intensity of production activities and vice versa; and - Production activities shift from subsistence agriculture to natural or forest resources exploitation or to other livelihood activities such as wage employment within and outside of the community. Natural Resources Accounts, using a SAM structure, record community economic activities at a point in time; it is a snapshot of economic activities in one year. It simply records production output, factors of production, destination of products, and investment/savings, in monetary terms. Sustainability of important factors of production or capital inputs such as natural resources remains to be determined. Assessing the sustainability of these resources requires constructing a dynamic model of natural resources stock and flow. This is the next component in the broader framework. 37 Natural Resources (Timber) Sustainability Model/Information simulates the stock and flow of resources as influenced by potential changes of consumption and production decisions by households over time. Model specifications include growth characteristics, harvest decisions (representing demand for natural resources), changes in stock and flow of resources, and indicators of sustainability. The outcome of the simulation provides a basis for intervention or policy options for both community decision-makers and national policy makers. The SAM helps assess potential impacts of those choices. Community/Household Consumption and Production Decision Alternatives Household consumption patterns and production activities in rural areas affect the flow and stock of natural resources. Internal characteristics and linkages with external factors, in turn, influence these consumption and production activities. Therefore, factors that influence household production and consumption activities directly or indirectly define the account. Internal characteristics and external factors relevant for this study are described below. Internal Characteristics and Endogenous Factors This includes household demographics, labor composition, household consumption and production preferences, and assets/properties. Brief descriptions of each component follow. 38 Household Demographics. Household size, age composition, level of education, gender ratio, family structure, religious affiliations, leadership, day-to-day management, and kinship relationships all influence the type and frequency of production activities and household consumption levels. In periods of scarcity or abundance, these demographic characteristics potentially influence decision-making and types of livelihood or production activities. Household Lzfior Composition. Rural household heads are generally unskilled laborers besides having farming skills. Barbier and L6pez (1998) hypothesized that off- farm or wage employment is directly proportional to size of landholding. The skill level determines the intensity or frequency of off-farm or wage employment. The level of education determines manpower capabilities. The male household head or husband traditionally conducts the decision-making, earning income, and production activities in rural households. Household Preferences. Preferences translate to choices of production activities and levels of consumption. Likewise, skill level and demographic characteristics influence preferences and vice versa. Household Assets or Properties. Inherited or acquired land generates income and wealth for rural farmers, if it is productive (Shields et al., 1993). Without these types of properties, households rely on small-scale income generating activities such as labor and wage employment (domestic helper, carpenter, masonry etc). Without these 39 opportunities, rural households resort to exploitation of natural resources in fisheries or forests. In this situation, open access or common pool resources substitute as important secondary sources of livelihood for rural households. Ownership status affects intensity of natural resource exploitation, and thus its stock and flow. Therefore, household characteristics affect the stock and flow of resources directly and indirectly via production and consumption activities. Community or village level accounts ought to reflect these influences. Household Well-being and Consumption One approach to identify what goes into the SAM is to understand what constitutes household well-being, represented by its consumption. Satisfaction of basic food, clothing and shelter needs of households determine household well-being. These needs are met either by own-production or by purchase of market commodities using income from production or both. Therefore, rural households' well-being is directly or indirectly derived from consumption of outputs in agriculture (A), forest—related natural resources (F) and market purchases (M), simply summarized as follows: Rural Household Economic Well-being: flC )=f(Ac, Fe, MC) (1) Where: C = consumption as measure of well-being which includes: Ac = agricultural goods consumed by households Fc = forest goods consumed by households, and Mc = market goods purchased and consumed by households. 40 Conceptually, conventional accounts reflect mostly the Mc component of household consumption plus hired labor and purchase of capital inputs, but ignore direct household consumption. This complete market orientation assumes that all food, clothing and shelter needs are marketed. It further assumes that market expenditures are equivalent to money income from production activities (that include natural resources exploitation). Equation (2) represents a mathematical expression of well-being formulated as market expenditures (Appendix A] presents more details): Market Expenditures: XPMiMc. = ZPAAAS) + ZPF;(FS) +21. - (wL + PKK + c) (2) where: 2PMiMc, = total market purchases/expenditures of households, where PM, = market price of purchased commodity i, and MC; refers to market commodity i purchased for consumption needs; EPA,(AS) = money income from sale of agricultural (A) commodity i where it is assumed that total agriculture output A = As, all output are marketed; PA, is the market price of agricultural commodity i and subscripts means sold or marketed; ZPF,(FS) = money income from sale of forest commodity i where it is assumed that total forest exploitation output F = F,, all outputs marketed; Pp, is market price of forest commodity i and subscripts means sold or marketed; XI, = total income from other production activities i; 41 ZPA,(AS) + XPMFS) +21; = total income of household from production activities, reflected in the market; wL + PKK + c = total expenditures of household, where w, PK, and c are wage rates of L, price of capital input K, and other costs of production activities, respectively. Since, Market Expenditures = Net Household Income, then XPrvrrMcr + (WL + PKK + C) = XPAIMS) + ZPFKFS) +le (3) An Mc equal to zero in Equation (2) and (3) implies that all production outputs are diverted to household consumption to meet essential consumption needs (In an economic sense, the opportunity cost of selling production output is greater than direct consumption). However, in most cases. Mc will not be zero because household production income must provide for essential expenses such as education, import of inputs and commodities from outside the community, and related needs available only at the market. Therefore, household consumption (representing well-being) includes both own-produced and market-purchased commodities. In this case the value of Equation ( l) is greater than Equation (2) fIC )=f(Ac, Fe, Me) > ZPMiMci (4) because some production outputs are directly consumed by households that do not enter the market. The right-hand-side of Equation (4) represents money income of households net of directly consumed production outputs, while the left-hand side includes market- purchased commodities and production outputs consumed by a household — hence, the 42 inequality. Therefore, the accounting system that assesses well-being should incorporate both marketed and non-marketed components of consumption. The mathematical models above assume that: 0 households satisfy welfare needs by substituting some market commodities with own produce, hence, there are commodities that do not enter the market; 0 households have two major sources of livelihood: agriculture and forest exploitation, and may shift to other types of livelihood such as wages/employment in the event that those two are not sufficient or constrained; and o households augment income from agriculture and forest exploitation with other non-land-based livelihood activities; Elements of the accounts are guided by these formulations (Equations 1 to 4). The household-expenditure function reveals consumption needs linked to outputs of production activities. In rural communities, households resort to various production activities at different times, as influenced by endogenous and exogenous factors. The next section shows simple models of these production activities. Household Production The household is the consumption as well as production center. These households own and lease agricultural land from landowners, and seasonally gain livelihood from 43 fishery and other non-land-based activities; otherwise, they exploit natural resources in the forest. These alternative opportunities promote shifts of production activities depending on the constraints. benefits, and costs involved. A number of factors influence the choice and intensity of any production activity: consumption needs; demographic characteristics (e. g., household size); income opportunities from outside, translated as opportunity cost of production; external factors such as market forces, government policies on land tenure, institutions within and from outside that affect the community; pressures from other groups outside the community (e.g., environmentalists. political groups, local governing authorities); and weather conditions and potential natural risks. At some times in household production, more effort goes to agriculture and at other times to the forest. If the opportunity cost of production in agriculture is high, a household will intensify production from the forest; otherwise, time will be devoted to non-land-based production activities. Equation (3) show Agricultural (A), Forest (F) and Other Livelihood (1) production options of households that show components for recording in the SAM: A, or F; or I, =/(L, K) (5) 44 Where i refers to a particular commodity production, and the factors of production that enters the SAM are: L = LH + LFa K = AK + FK + MK LH = LA+ LF + L. And AK = AA +AF + A. FK = F A +FF + F, MK = MA +MF + M LH = summarizes hired labor employed in agricultural production, LA, or hired labor for forest exploitation, LF; and hired labor for other livelihood activities, Ll. If LH is zero, L is simply family labor, Lpa; not all labor types are employed in one production activity; Lpa = family labor employed in all production activities, not accounted in conventional accounts; K = total capital inputs coming from agriculture, AK, forest exploitation, FK, and purchased from the market, MK; AK = capital used in production may include AA, AF, AL or part of agricultural production output used as capital for agricultural production, forest exploitation, and for other livelihood, respectively; FK = capital used in production may include F A, F p, FL or part of forest exploitation output used as capital for agricultural production, forest exploitation, and for other livelihood, respectively; and 45 MK = capital inputs purchased from the market, used for agriculture (MA). forest exploitation (Mr). and other livelihood (Mr). considered imports to the community. Equation (5) implies that factors of production employed by households are common factors, movable from one livelihood opportunity to the other. In the absence of empirical evidence, equations for L and K are suggested to be linear or portraying perfect substitutability between hired and family labor, and between capital for agriculture, forest, and other livelihoods, respectively. These kinds of relationships promote shifting of production activities. This relationship further emphasizes its relevance in valuation of production components that do not enter the market. Not all outputs in agriculture (A) or forest exploitation (F) or other livelihood (I) are marketed; a portion is directly consumed by the household or reinvested as capital inputs. Production outputs are distributed as follows: A = As + Ac + AK (6) F = Fs + Fc + FK I = 1s + 1c + 1K Where, in all the expressions (Equation 6) above, the subscripts, c, K refer to marketed (sold), household-bound, and reinvested as capital input, respectively. The last two output destinations may not involve monetary transactions, but are needed to reflect household activities in economic accounts. Appendix A.2 provides simple measures of natural 46 resources in consumption and production, useful for comparing conventional accounts and the SAM developed in this study. Finally, certain production constraints (or opportunities) force households to shift from one production activity to another. Appendix A.3 presents a simple mathematical relationship describing household decisions to shift from one production activity to another. The shifting and frequency of production create uncertainty on the outcome of resources, most especially open access or common pool resources such as forests, where exploitation can be uncontrolled. An accounting of natural resources exploitation that considers these shifts can aid decisions in terms of sustainability of consumption and production. Consumption and production activities are endogenous factors that are affected by internal and external factors. These external factors influencing consumption and production decision are discussed next. External (Exogenous) Factors Exogenous factors either constrain or increase consumption and production activities. These external factors become instruments in regulating resource exploitation, and hence, useful (tools) for sustainability objectives. These include local institutions. government, and market forces. 47 Locgl Community a_nd External Institutions. Property and tenurial relations, common property management, socio-cultural affiliations, political institutions, labor exchange arrangements and production relations influence income generating strategies and thus, level of activity in farms, forests or other livelihood (Appendini et al., 1999). Government (Policies). Policies on land tenure and ownership, access to forest resources, regulation of production levels, rural credit, and landholding in rural communities directly and indirectly influence household activities. Market forces (Rest of the World). Prices of consumer goods and production outputs, market wage rates, and input prices generally influence decision-making in terms of consumption and production activities. and value of natural resources. In situations where consumption/exploitation of natural resources, particularly timber, is not sustainable, decision- and policy-makers use these exogenous factors to regulate or promote natural resources exploitation. Impacts of such intervention on the rural economy is recorded in the SAM, and further analyzed through multiplier analysis. Discussion on this extension of matrix component (multiplier analysis) is set aside for a later discussion. Hence, the SAM is necessary but not a sufficient instrument for assessing long-term rural well-being. 48 Natural Resource Accounts Natural resource accounts provide appraisal and evaluation functions, and management decision-making functions. They are primarily useful at the local level, and as input for policy-making at the broader scale (i.e., regional and national levels). The appraisal and evaluation functions require those important variables, such as consumption and production accounts that affect the stock and flow of resources enter the account system. Thus, accounts must include how much of production outputs are marketed, directly consumed, and reinvested in own production. The account structure must clearly reflect these important variables. The World Bank framework on social accounting matrix, or SAM (Pyatt and Round, 1985), closely captures the dynamics of these rural household activities, and aggregates accounts at the community level. The standard structure of a SAM includes production activities, factors of production (represented by L and K), institutions [represented by household and community expenditures on Me, capital formation and human capital (representing capital)], and the rest of the world. SAM Components Derived from Consumption and Production Functions The number of account components depends on the purpose of SAM construction. Most socioeconomic studies attempt to evaluate distribution of benefits over categories of households, and in this study, on land ownership. An extension covered by this study evaluates the impact on natural resources. Figure 2 summarizes the model structure of the 49 SAM at the community level. The rows of the SAM contain receipt accounts of community production activities, factors of production, institutions, capital accounts, and the rest of the world. The column elements represent expenditures made by these accounts. The intersection of each row and column (sub-matrix) represents a "transaction" account, implying receipts or expenditures. Empty sub-matrices can mean two things: either there are no relevant transactions at the community level or there were no transactions recordable. The numbers in parentheses represent row and column (r, c) for labeling transactions. Transactions are described starting from the upper leftmost to the right and moving downward. 1. 2. Production activities (1,1). At the village level, this consists of agricultural farming (A), forest exploitation (F), and other livelihood activities (I) that may include fishery, retail stores and others. Institutions purchase or directly consume outputs of production (Ac, As; Fc, F5; 1c, 1,), recorded as transactions (1,3). Part of production goes to savings/investment [AK, FK, transactions (1,4)], whether it is man-made (m) or natural (n). The rest of outputs are exported (1,5). This sub-matrix ("transaction") also records inter-activity demand for outputs. However, in the case of the community/household, most production outputs are sold or exported outside of the village (1,5). Hence, only a few activities have input-output interactions. firetors of production - accounts for family labor, hired labor, and capital used in production activity [f(L,K)]. Transactions (2,1), the intersection of Factors of Production Accounts and Production Activities, summarize payments to capital or capital value-added, and labor or labor value-added. Capital accounts include tangible and produced capital (man-made and natural). 50 #:qu wcscsooo< 38m £56.50 05 he 220.com .N oSmE ask a a_eaaéoo V0 2.63 05 .3 sex m .8350 58:: :o_8_=E=uu< :o_u~_uo._gn< cos—aficion— .356 825.850 3.5380 mac—0:030... 9.085.— mflosomg; BEoéwEm 20:552— .8532 038-52 3:30 .33 3:: .33 2.5: cocoavoi .«o 22%..— Same “5920?; .550 :80: box»...— .§E>o_aEm own? 5.5.834". 395“— main: :3 3233‘ concave.“— ~ 9 n ndraaau N 263 13:30 2053:?— =ozu=v2m 82>30< 2: he «may. . . he £28m concave...— o m w n N — 8.9% 22am 851$ E5252 Sauocum< 8:51:35— 51 3. Institutions - includes households as recipients of income from employing factors of production (2,1 ). From the mathematical model, transactions (3,2) records de and rK, where w refers to domestic wage rate and r refers to value of capital. Other than receipts from employing factors of production, institutions receive remittances from external wage employment (wa), recorded in (3,5). Transfer payments/subsidies from government (3,3) adds to household receipts. Government taxes may provide subsidies for local production (3,1). On the expenditure side, this major account also records household purchase of production outputs or expenditures on locally produced market goods (1,3); household tax payments to government (3,2) and imports (5,3) of consumption goods. Insertion of direct use by household of own-production is one notable extension of the SAM for this major component. Thus, transaction (1,3) includes households as destinations of production outputs. Chapter 5 provides further explanations on this insertion. Institutions' factor income, receipt from remittances, and transfers or subsidies are allocated among consumption expenditures or demand for commodities ( 1,3), savings, and contribution to community cooperatives (4,3). Household savings (4,3) are further allocated to physical capital investment or human capital enhancement (4,4). 52 4. gm! - On the receipt side, this account records investment/savings (AK, FK), recorded as transaction (1,4). On the expenditure side, this account records depreciation and accumulation of both man-made and natural capital, labeled as transaction (4,4). Human capital, normally an independent account in other SAMs, is under this major category of capital. This major account also records expenditures on enhancement of human capital (i.e., manpower skill development), useful for evaluating manpower potentials of the community; Imputed value for the use of natural resources also appears as factor of production (in 4,1). Hence, inclusion of the natural resource accounts revises the standard SAM. Capital and other inputs purchased from outside are reflected as "Purchase of imported input" (5.1) from the Rest of the World. Rest of the world (ROW) - includes purchase of imported inputs (MK) for production activities (5,1) and expenditures on market commodities (MC) for consumption (5.3); and Receipts and Expenditure accounts must balance hence, the SAM is a square matrix. Each row total should equal corresponding column totals. However, in practical situations, they do not balance so that a Deficit/Surplus account is included. Thus. Deficit/Surplus and Totals are simply balancing accounts. 53 Therefore, this study introduces three innovations to the conventional SAM. First, SAM, traditionally used at the national (macro) scale, is applied to a rural community setting. Second, in principle, the community SAM in this study includes accounts of natural resources stocks and flows. Depreciation and depletion of natural capital becomes a novel entry into the SAM. not traditionally included in most SAM structure found in literature. This account provides indicators for community decision-makers on the status of natural resources when compared to investment in capital resources, and natural resources accumulation. Third, inclusion of direct household consumption of production outputs not traditionally included in conventional SAM. Hence, the overall structure and components of the SAM resembles conventional SAM, with modifications as described. However, the structure of the production sector is not the same with conventional or industry-type input-output matrix. In industry-type input output, government and business are distinct production activities. In this study, these accounts were treated as part of household production activities hence, the SAM creates a different form of aggregation. Estimation of SAM entries, whether marketed or non-marketed, requires common measures and valuation, which is the focus of the next section. Measurement, Valuation and Aggregation to the SAM This study assumes that consumption needs and market transactions guide households in applying measures and values. That is, household decisions to directly 54 consume or market production outputs depend on money income needs. From an analyst's perspective, this implies a balanced budget. In principle, aggregated household expenditures should equal aggregated total receipts, mirroring the structure in the SAM. At the household level, the balanced budget or income-expenditure identity equation ( a possible measure of well-being) will be: RH,- = EH]- (i.e., Receipts of Household j = Expenditures of Household j) or XPN(A,+AC+AK) +ZP1.‘.(FS+FC+FK) +221, = w(LA+L1:+L[) +PKK + c + 2PM.MC, (6) Therefore, EPA,(A,) = total value of agriculture production. marketed and non-marketed ZPF,(F.) = total value of forest exploitation, , marketed and non-marketed EPA,(A, -Ac-AK) = EPA,(A,), is the value of marketed component of agricultural production, equal to net income from agricultural production, ZPF,(F.-Fc-FK) = ZPF,(FS), is the value of marketed component of forest production, or net income from forest exploitation. Hence, non-market-transacted components: EPA,(AC+AK) = non-market-transacted component of agricultural production, and ZPF,(FC+FK) = non-market-transacted component of forest exploitation. These formulations suggest a basis for valuation of non-marketed components of household consumption and use of natural capital. Equation (6) clearly, delineates non- marketed components that do no appear in conventional accounts. In a later chapter, these are calculated in order to measure proportions that are not reflected in conventional 55 national accounts. Specifically, percentages of natural capital depreciation and non- marketed components are computed. Subscripts c and K represent outputs directly consumed, and used as capital inputs for production activities, respectively. Thus, measurement and valuation depends on the consumption or production commodity in question. Measurement follows the mode of measurement and market transactions by households, and valuation is principally market-based. Appendix A4 lists other valuation methods applied to forest resources. Likewise, valuation of the non-marketed component will depend on the commodity and mode of transaction. Based on the expressions above, market transactions become the basis for measurement and valuation of production outputs, whether for household consumption or reinvested in production. Physical outputs of all production activities are valued at market price P...- [where: x = agriculture (A) or forest (F) output]. Hence, the total of household income and expenditures represents aggregated income and expenditures by the community or village, representing the grand total of Receipts and Expenditures in the SAM: .V 2RH,= I=| EH, for allj = 1,..., N .v i=1 Where: RH,~ = receipts of household j from production activities EH,- = expenditures of household j for all its production activities N = total number of households in the community 56 The aggregation to the SAM follows the above formulation where receipts of all households are aggregated for the whole community. To conform to the SAM structure, the sum of production activities and factors of production of households become the basis for aggregation to the whole community. The aggregation in the SAM in turn becomes the input for aggregation at the regional or national level. Thus, the structure and valuation provide possible linkage to national accounts. In the process of construction of the SAM, the natural resources component of consumption and production activities were measured and valued. The next step in the framework development is to arrive at a model for assessing sustainability of natural resources consumption recorded in the SAM. The next section covers this component of framework development. Measuring Sustainability of Natural Resources The demand for natural resources by households and the community directly translates to levels of harvest or exploitation. Levels of harvest that exceed the growth rate potentially reduce the stock for future production, and the converse occurs with below-growth-rate harvest, and dominant product sustainability (Gale and Cordray, 1991) implies that harvest should not exceed growth considering other factors constant. Natural growth, harvest levels, and damages translate to physical depreciation or appreciation of resources over time. The SAM provides information at a point in time - one year. Information on stock and flow recorded and projected over time provides information on 57 sustainability of natural resources. A series of SAM models for several periods for the same region would provide a trend of natural resources exploitation. For planning purposes, analysts make projections in order to predict effects of varying levels of exploitation. Most literature suggests the idea of determining a steady state - using mathematical optimal control theory — of resource exploitation over time in order to assess sustainability (Pezzey, 1992). The general idea is to assume that households behave to maximize their welfare (consumption) in each period. Natural resources capital is introduced as constraint in the maximization function. The optimal decision criterion for sustainability of resources is that the resource extraction at each period t, such that the stock of resources is non-declining over the planning horizon. However, this approach is conceptual. Simulation modeling provides an alternative tool for assessing sustainability. Its advantage lies in the use of empirical data obtained from inventories and surveys. The SAM provides the initial values to the simulation model. In order to conduct simulation, natural resources stock and flow and human exploitation are modeled in a dynamic fashion. Figure 3 summarizes a simulation model for assessing natural resources stock and flow. The model starts with a beginning or opening stock of resources, timber in this study, and ends with a record of closing stock at year's end. Additions to opening stock come from natural growth of timber (from both existing stand and new growths) and forest expansion (through reforestation or afforestation). Reductions come from harvests (obtained from household/community demand), natural stand mortality and other natural occurrences including forest fire. The closing stock for the year becomes opening stock 58 of the next year. Additions less reductions produce net changes in stock. The net-change- in-stock records the depreciation or appreciation of the resource. Balance of addition and reduction over the years translate to sustainability of the resource base. A negative net- change-in-stock implies over-exploitation. In this latter case, policy or decision options suggest reduced consumption of natural resources, a shift of production activity to non- natural resource-based livelihood, import of natural-resource-based consumption output, price intervention, or government regulation (see Figure l). NAT RAL E IR E A NT N T R Year 1 Year 2 ...Year 3 Opening Stock _—> Opening Stock —_* Opening Stock Plus Same Items as Same Items as Y 1 Y -1 Additions ear car It Net Change in = (”OM/7 Stock Plantation Development Less Reductions Harvest . Harvest Wastes Stand Mortality (natural E ual damage and tire) Closing Stock Closing Stock Closing Stock 6 Figure 3. Simulation model for the stock and flow of natural resources (adopted from Repetto et al., 1989 and DENR, 1991). In summary, this chapter lays the foundation for the empirical study by developing a conceptual framework for various aspects of account development at the 59 community level. The economic transactions of households at the community level become the basis for defining elements of the accounts. The accounts structured in the SAM format capture economic activities at the household level, whether marketed or non-marketed. Each account element is measured and valued based on household transactions in the market. The natural resource simulation model provides the link for assessing the impact of internal and external factors on the sustainability of natural resources over time. Chapter 4 provides a procedure for constructing the SAM and multipliers helpful for analyzing impacts of exogenous (external) changes on household consumption and production and resource sustainability. The chapter also describes details of the data collection procedure that includes survey tools at the household and community level, in order to construct the SAM for this study. Chapter 5 present results of analysis and describes the simulation procedure to evaluate sustainability of community resources. 60 CHAPTER 4 DATA COLLECTION. ACCOUNTING STRUCTURE. AND LINKAGES TO RESOURCE SUSTAINABILITY The previous chapter laid out the conceptual framework, the conceptual structure of the accounting system using the SAM, and the multi-period forest simulation model along with associated linkages. These served as a guide in the empirical study and data collection procedures described in this chapter. Further, data collection required significant effort due to interactions with members of the community, including local leaders and governing bodies, and this required multiple extended visits to different sites. Data accuracy and precision required checking and counter-checking for consistency that reflects the reality of a community. Surveys and interviews effectively generate information on consumption, production, and market activities of households, while focus group discussions generate a knowledge base on community institutions and external influential factors. Resource inventory is the other source of data needed to generate the stock and flow accounts of natural resources. The next section describes these data collection and measurement processes. Data Collection Processes The source of data for natural resource accounts using the SAM framework at the community level is of first importance. The basic unit for collecting data, discussed in Chapter 3, was the household, the final demand or consumption point and production 61 center. Building the SAM from household data to aggregate at the community level required surveying households' demographic characteristics, consumption patterns and production activities, and developing a knowledge base of community level institutions and external influences (e.g. market and government policies). The data collection process was a crucial component in account development. Survey Process The process of survey/interview involved three stages. The first stage, Community Familiarization, required interaction with community residents, local leaders, and governing organizations. The second stage, Focus Group Discussions (FGD), covered assessment of the economic structure and institutions in order to develop a knowledge base of economic and other production activities. The F GD was the venue for explaining the intent of the survey/ interview and for creating an initial knowledge base on the community's economic structure and institutions. The third stage, Household Survey-Interview, involved interviews of sample households to obtain data on demographic characteristics, consumption, and production. The first stage involved simple and informal consultations and interactions with community residents. The next sections discuss details of the last two stages. Focus Group Discussion or Survey. The process of determining what could and what could not be included in the household interviews required preliminary discussions and consultations with the community leaders through FGD. The group discussion 62 focused on understanding household consumption patterns, production activities, and household purchases (or expenditures). Therefore, a flexible structure of discussion was employed to appear less formal and varied for the five study communities. However, the group discussion centered on the following concerns of the study: On development of natural resource accounts: Draw feedback on the significance of simplified and community-based natural resource accounts; On conduct of household interviews: Solicit suggestions on the appropriateness and precision of draft questions pertaining to demographics, expenditure and consumption patterns. production activities. and marketing activities; On measurement and valuation of resources: Solicit infomration on more common products, both in agriculture and forests, sold or consumed, their units of measures, valuation methods employed, and periods of work and leisure; and On external influences: Draw out infonnation on market, institutional and government policy influences on household and community activities. Based on this four-point focus, the FGD involved a few steps: Initial community consultation and introduction of the research, Solicitation and screening of focus group participants, Scheduling of group discussion, 63 0 Actual F GD, and 0 Synthesis of discussion. Other than meals and transportation expenses during meetings, no incentives were provided to focus group discussion and survey participants. Recommended participants to the FGD include community and people's organization officers. Table 1 shows the venue and number of participants in the FGD. Table 1. Study site and number of participants of focus group discussions in 5 communities. Focus Group Venue Number of Participants San Pascual San Pascual, Basud, Camarines Norte 12 Mercedes Colasi, Mercedes, Camarines Norte 8 Tible Tible, Sipocot, C amarines Sur 6 Comments on the interview questionnaire by F GD participants comprised the final stage of its technical revision. Discussions also included issues on appropriateness and structuring of questions so that they were not offensive or too technical for rural households. Auxiliary activities such as obtaining price levels and standard units of measures used in transactions within and outside the village were conducted toward the end of the survey process. Household Survey. The household survey or interviews followed from the F GD. Considering the literacy level, a face-to-face interview was deemed more appropriate for rural households over other forms of survey. Interviewers were recruited who were well acquainted with the questionnaire and the rural community (or at least familiar with the 64 route of the survey). All interviewers were technical personnel of the Department of Environment and Natural Resources based in C amarines Norte and C amarines Sur. Some important considerations in household surveys are: Orient and train interviewers on how to handle and present the questionnaire so that it is not offensive to respondents, yet obtain the desired precision of answers; Focus the interview on residents and dependents of the household (family members independent of the household are not covered) to avoid underestimating or overestimating consumption and production information for the household; List of replacement (substitute) respondents must be handy for interviewers in case of unavailability of chosen sample respondent; A household respondent must be familiar with the consumption and production information, and this may not necessarily be the household head; Although an appointment time is not critical in rural households, advance notice of interview schedule must be passed on so that intended respondents are available; and Permission and cooperation of local leaders must be obtained before interviews can proceed. 65 The Survey Questionnaire The synthesized outputs of focus group discussions were incorporated into the final survey questionnaire. The questionnaire consisted of four sections: consumption and household assets, production or livelihood activities, environmental awareness and leisure time, and household demographics. A number of steps were undertaken in order to develop the survey questionnaire: 0 After review by the dissertation guidance committee, the questionnaire was presented to a group of technical personnel who had previous experience in questionnaire-based surveys; o The questionnaire was introduced during focus group discussions as a screening process to determine the usefulness of each question; 0 Questions were subsequently revised to focus only on consumption and livelihood or production activities; 0 To test the duration of the questionnaire, a resident of a forest community inside the University of the Philippines Los Bar’ios Forest Reserve was interviewed, and flaws in Filipino language were corrected in the process; and o The questionnaire was pre-tested by five randomly selected members of each of the five communities in the study area. All pre-test respondents were excluded from the final household respondents. The final questionnaire incorporated modifications suggested by interviewers after the pre-testing. 66 The next sections provide brief descriptions of each questionnaire section. The final questionnaire (English Version) is in Appendix B. 1. The actual questionnaire in the local language (Tagalog) consisted of 45 questions, a total of 25 pages and averages I to 1-1/2 hours of interview time. Some of the questions are "check/verification questions" that aid respondents in recalling consumption and expenditures over the preceding one year. These questions were useful in the process of data consolidation. a. Household Consumption Questions The basic needs (or consumption) component, was classified a priori into food, clothing, and shelter, and focused on dissecting a household's daily subsistence and other regular needs. This detailed approach obtained information on components of consumption activities that draw directly or indirectly from natural (forest) resources. The implicit proposition underlying this approach was that consumption by rural households was predominantly composed of non-traded goods that were not reflected in traditional national income accounts, thereby underestimating capital consumption, or depreciation. b. Household Assets Questions These questions elicited information on produced or non-produced (natural) household assets whether purchased from traditional markets or produced by households without passing through market channels. This complemented the actual 67 physical inventory or resource assessment that was conducted by community residents, and identified the destinations of outputs from various production activities. There was also an emphasis on getting data on expenditures for these assets. for purposes of determining total wealth. 0. Production Activities Questions Livelihood or production activities consisted of two major types, agriculture and forestry, and other minor, non-land-based activities. Questions for eliciting information on these income-generating activities (agriculture, forestry, and other minor income-generating activities) were asked separately. From the point of view of the study, the intent was to describe the various patterns of production activities. Questions on production activities included quantity of outputs, their prices, costs and returns, destination, and whether or not these are forest resources. Ancillary income generating activities (other than minor-income generating activities) which were assumed to cover for insufficiency of other livelihood sources were treated as the fourth "livelihood" activity. d. Leisure and Environmental Awareness Questions The questionnaire included three questions on health and sanitation to briefly evaluate household awareness of global environmental concerns such as water pollution and carbon dioxide emissions from forests. 68 Types of leisure and hours spent were included to determine number hours of work by households. e. DemographiC/Socio-economic Characteristics Questions A table matrix summarized demographic and socio-economic questions for the household (See Appendix Table 8.1 p 25). The table matrix included number of household occupants, family head, spouse, dependent children and extended family members and their age, sex, civil status, education, employment, and average monthly income. Determining the Sample Size Communities adjoining the Bicol National Park have a total land area of 5,201 hectares (Figure 5). The study area covered a cluster of 5 out of 10 communities surrounding the Bicol National Park. These five communities, all on the eastern side of the Park are: Province Municipality Communig Peoples' Organization Camarines Norte Basud 1.San Pascual CPEU, Inc. Mercedes 2. Pambuahn MUFFIN 3. Tarum 4. Colasi Camarines Sur Sipocot 5. Tible TIBKOI 69 Located in Region 5, Bicol Region, of the Philippines, all five communities were treated as an integrated community—based forest management project. Contracted to three different People's Organizations (POs) by the C ommunity-based Forest Management (C BFM) Program coordinators, the project is treated administratively as one organization. Thus, in the context of the Bicol National Park all five were treated as a "super-community." Likewise in this study, the five communities were treated as one; hence, a single SAM was developed. Based on community Chieftain records in 1998, the five communities consist of 1,493 households, and an estimated population of 9,430. Table 2 summarized total households by community, total population and land area of the five communities, including sample size for each community. Households in these five communities shift activities from agriculture, forestry to fisheries. Households in interior communities such as San Pascual and Tible are predominantly coconut, rice and root crops farmers while coastal communities such as Pambuhan, Tarum and Colasi also diversify to fishing. Most of these activities are seasonal so that households resort to other livelihood activities such as carpentry, masonry, retail trading, and other artisanal activities such as broom-making and basket weaving using materials from non—timber products from the forest. The survey recorded 26 other livelihood activities (see Appendix C8) based on surveyed households. 70 :owwom 32m 05 E scam Econ“ Z 82m 05 mo 02m 5033 05 :o @882 Be 895888 beam 2E. .v ocswE .1. 0. Av 5 .3 ¢ e53 5: E . 3 see “55:: 2&5 ‘ execs 0.: 25:2 cone sod 5.32 .51.: 2&5 . :60 O oU 92222300 3.3.22.3. 39:23.. 3.2.9.23: .ov.o_...nEm 2053...»... n .3352 338-52 .3230 San.— out: canal. 3.8a“. :ozuzvocm ..o 32am... N sadgaaau mmOfimOdmO Emmu .30 .5233: 550 -Nmo.o.o.o.o :33. .20 33.3... ...OXIO .eufionEM emu? .00. 353:: :o:3.o...xw :30... coco—:3...— wEEEH. ..cm< mu.:>:u<:o..o w n. — a: .22; 2.... 3.3 22.2.? 3.3.2.. “n.3,”... EoCua 2.20:3. .. a a. .. u a. nos—«>zcauoaeioaaaocuut. b o n v n u _ 3.231.123 an.— 78 Measurement and Valuation of SAM Inputs There are two fundamental issues to resolve in natural resource accounting involving the village or household economy: (I) varying units of measure for consumption commodities and production outputs, and (2) how to value non-traded or non-marketed commodities. Natural resource goods and services beyond these commodities are not addressed. This study describes approaches for the above issues that are applicable to the five communities under study. Application to other areas or communities was also envisioned in this approach. In the community, units of measure of marketed commodities vary because of different forms of transactions. In order to resolve these variations, the most logical approach was to convert physical outputs into monetary units: using local currency, the Philippine peso. Use of monetary value (Pesos) provided a common unit for aggregating dissimilar products and activities, a fundamental requirement to be included in national income (and/or natural resource) accounting. lmputation of value (based on local currency) was an approach taken for non- marketed commodities. Of particular importance are natural resources used as capital inputs in production and use of family labor as substitute for hired labor. Chapter 3 identified two standard approaches: shadow pricing and market price of substitutes. Peskin (1996) and Vincent (1998) recommended use of market value or opportunity cost of labor (still market price) to impute value for natural resources. In some instances. 79 employing the suggested opportunity cost approach tends to overvalue the resource. For instance, a household decision to produce own-fuelwood indicated that opportunity cost of hired labor is higher than its (fuelwood) production value. On the other hand, James (1996) recommended the use of market valuation for accounting purposes geared for policy analysis as opposed to opportunity cost based on labor wages. This study valued family labor as the residual value of production after deducting input costs. For valuing timber, several studies supported the use of stumpage value (DENR, 1991; IRG et al., 1996). In the perspective of economic efficiency, stumpage valuation overestimates asset value because it disregards future tree growth and most likely included monopoly rents in a developing country setting (IRG et al., 1996). Calculation of the value of fuelwood, which has both a traded and a non-traded role, can be based on market value of delivered processed wood fuel less costs involved (equivalent to "stumpage"). Imputing value based on family labor used in wood fuel production may be used by conducting time and motion on fuelwood production. Thus, the SAM entries (including natural resources exploitation) were in monetary terms using market prices and imputing values of non-marketed commodities using market prices as a starting point. Resources Sustainability and Community Well-being Interactions Accounting for exploitation of natural resources is one focus of this study. Changes in household demographics, consumption, production, and external factors 80 affect the stock and flow of natural resources (timber) in the community and vice versa. Different levels of exploitation lead to different patterns of natural stock and flow. Exogenous controls may mitigate undesirable use levels or enhance desirable ones. Subsequently, controlling exogenous factors creates changes in various endogenous factors (i.e., production and consumption) and the well-being of households. All these interactions and changes can be reflected in the SAM. Thus, the SAM, ceteris paribus, becomes the information system at a point in time. Assessing the linkage between resources sustainability and community well-being over time involved a two-stage procedure. The first stage required simulating the stock and flow of natural resources as affected by various options of exploitation, taking into account the goal to sustain well-being. The second stage was to assess the impact on well-being of controlling/changing exogenous variables, taking into account the goal of sustaining natural resources (timber) stock and flow. This second stage measures the impact of a unit change of exogenous variables on endogenous factors affecting household well-being (here described as consumption and production patterns). These processes or stages are described below. Simulating Natural Resources Stock and F low The simulation procedure was designed to assess the sustainability of various options for harvesting timber resources, based on a sustainable harvest per year. The simulation model was also designed to evaluate the rate of appreciation and/or 81 depreciation (physical and monetary) of timber resources affected by community activities. This became the management tool for assessing the sustainability of forest resources as affected by various activities in community forestry. The procedure required information on the initial stock and flow of resources. The survey of households and focus group discussions provided information on consumption and production activities. An assessment and inventory of resource stock (using the stand and stock table created by the POs as proxy) completed the other side of account development — the resource base. The summarized list of products extracted and sold or consumed became the master list of resources for inventory. Gathering this data required almost the same amount of time as household surveys. The first step in the process was to define natural resource processes, and how human production activities affected these resources. These processes were translated into a simulation model that forecasts trends of resources, as driven by human economic activities. Ideally, the whole human-natural resource-system interaction should be modeled, but the resulting complex network and data needs far exceeded resources available for this study. Such a design will require enormous amount of data. Hence, the focus was on forest resources. Specifically, the focus was on timber resources, because no other inventory data were available for other forest resources. The source of stock and flow information for devel0ping the timber resources simulation model were the stand and stock tables (see Appendix Tables B. 1-3) from three POs developed for their 25-year planning period. 82 The basic model for the simulation was the conceptual framework adapted by Delos Angeles et al. (1995) for timber resources in the Philippines, similar to the reconciliation account of Canada (Statistics Canada, 1997). Its major components were opening stock, closing stock and net change in stock of various forest resources for every period. Opening stock plus net change in stock within the year yields the closing stock. The model incorporated resource characteristics such as growth rate, natural mortality, damage, and harvest options of the community on the periodic flow of resources. Thus, the measure of depreciation or appreciation could be negative or positive change in stock -— an indicator of sustainability - for the 25-year project duration. This approach was modeled using spreadsheet simulation in Microsoft Excel. The simplification required assumptions that other components of the forest system are not significantly affected by natural resources exploitation. An alternative graphical simulation model, using software such as STELLA (HPS, 1996) may take into account the complexity of the forest system by incorporating linkages with important natural resources such as soils. However, this approach would require further steps in modeling that are beyond the scope of this study. Evaluating Exogenous Impacts on the SAM The SAM is a snapshot or an account of receipts and expenditures at one point in time. It cannot provide concrete answers to questions of sustainability of resources and 83 well-being over time because most changes brought about by external factors appear only over a longer period, beyond the one-year data period of the SAM. A supplementary process that makes use of SAM information is to simulate impacts from changes in the SAM over the short term, by controlling exogenous variables. This makes use of the linkages between exogenous factors and the SAM represented by multipliers. The procedure involves identifying controllable exogenous variables in order to satisfy sustainability objectives. Options include reducing consumption/production, shifiing production, importing, changing prices, government regulation, or expanding the forest (see Figure l). The desired goal is to sustain resources and maximize welfare. The option to choose depends on which linkage in the SAM will create the most desired impact. Thus, multiplier analysis involves evaluating which among the options will be effective in attaining those goals. Results of such analysis are discussed in the next chapter. This procedure makes use of the multiplier matrix of endogenous variables to assess impact of exogenous variables. SAM Multiplier Matrix The multiplier matrix is developed in two stages. In the first stage. the SAM elements are structured into endogenous and exogenous accounts. The latter, in this study, include Government and Rest of the World. Segregating these endogenous and exogenous accounts is critical in evaluating the impact of changes in the community economy and on natural resources. These model proceeds with two assumptions: 84 0 Income and production changes as a result of exogenous introductions are strictly proportional (linear); and 0 Mostly exogenous factors, such as government and market, trigger changes in the village economy by influencing production and consumption. Then the base SAM is converted to a proportion matrix, or average-expenditure propensities (Taylor and Adelman, 1996), by dividing each value in the account matrix by expenditure totals (each element divided by its corresponding column totals). The exogenous share or average propensities for leakage (AL) is separated from endogenous shares to produce a sub-matrix of endogenous share (A5 matrix). In effect, the SAM can be expressed as the product of A-matrix and endogenous incomes/expenditures. This implies that row and column sums must be equal — (or as Pyatt and Round, 1985 stated, injections must equal leakages). In the second stage, the average expenditure multiplier (A5) is converted to a Leontief-type multiplier derived from the mathematical relationship between income and expenditures as follows: YE: A5 )7], + x Where: YE = vector of endogenous incomes or receipts; A5 = vector of endogenous average expenditure propensities; Y1. = vector ofexpenditure totals, referring to column totals in the account matrix; and x = exogenous income changes (introductions). Since, in the SAM YE: y‘ If Then, YE = (I - AEr'x Or ME = (II ' AEl'l Where: ME = Leontief-type endogenous income multiplier 6 A5 S 1 Thus, accounting multiplier matrix, (ME), originates from the average (expenditure) propensities (A5) that measure the direct effects of exogenous introductions on endogenous accounts in the SAM. However, the multiplier impact is greater than the original exogenous change. Stone (1985) and Pyatt and Round (1985) decomposed the total effect to reveal three types of effects: direct, indirect and cross effects (or similarly called induced effects), decomposition of which is also presented in Defoumy and Thorbecke (1984). Thus, any innovation or policy change (i.e. transfer of management of forest resources to the community) affects economic activity within the community, and thus impacts on resources. Linkages between consumption, production, and exogenous factors determine the impacts of these multipliers. Chapter 5 further elaborates on these impacts. 86 Secondary Sources of Information and Place of Study In addition to the FGD, face-to-face survey, and gathering of resource information, auxiliary information was obtained from various sources. Reports of NRMP Community Base Forest Management Annual Working Plan (AWP), Forest Land Use Plan (FLUP), inventory and assessment of the community forestry. ENRAP Phase I and [I provided regional and national estimates of resources. Various government institutions that manage community forestry, non-govemment organizations that assist the community in the 3-5 year build-up period, and the community organization itself were contacted for accounting validation. Household surveys were done in the five communities in Camarines Provinces namely Tible, San Pascual and Pambuhan, Tarum and Colasi. All these sites border the Bicol National Park in Region V. Finally, basic formulation of the accounting and simulation models were conducted at Michigan State University. In summary, this chapter outlined the procedures for applying the conceptual framework for natural resources accounting at the community level. The data collection procedures included community interaction, focus group discussions, survey instrument design, and household survey. Construction of the SAM involved mostly aggregating survey responses of 20% households in five communities, and the rest were secondary data obtained from the three peoples' organizations (POs). Assessing sustainability of natural resources required developing a simulation model for natural resources 87 specifically timber. Finally, this chapter outlined the procedure for assessing the impacts of exogenous changes on the endogenous variables on the SAM by making use of the SAM multiplier matrix. Results of these procedures are discussed in the next chapter. 88 CHAPTER 5 RESULTS AND DISCUSSION This chapter discusses the results of the SAM development, the simulation of natural resource exploitation (recorded in the SAM), and effects of exogenous interventions/injections on the elements of the SAM through a multiplier analysis. The first section describes the construction of the SAM that incorporated non-marketed production outputs and natural resources exploitation. The matrix format captures the economic structure and linkages of various actors in the community economic system. The second section describes the simulation modeling results of forest resources (timber) exploitation as affected by various levels of exploitation (harvest). The third section focused on evaluating the impact of changing exogenous factors on the SAM. Throughout the chapter, the discussion centers on aspects of account development and usefulness of the SAM for sustainability analysis. Developing the Social Accounting Matrix The initial direction of this research was to develop a SAM for each of the five communities that buffer a national park, and for possible replication in communities outside of the study area. However, in the process it became apparent that developing a separate SAM for each community would only increase the complexity of the analysis. but would not significantly change overall results and interpretations. Thus. all 89 information obtained from five communities was consolidated into one account matrix. The option to consolidate all five communities stems from two important justifications. First, the assessment focuses on the impact of forest exploitation activities on the overall second-growth forest that buffers the Bicol National Park rather than the jurisdiction of each community. A single account conveniently accomplishes this assessment, instead of evaluating several accounts derived for all five communities. Second, aggregating these five communities introduces more variation of livelihood activities. In this situation, it mirrors a number of production activities that are likely to occur in many other villages. Therefore, consolidating five villages as a "super-village" provides an advantage of evaluating impacts of various forms of production activities. The social accounting matrix was developed by synthesizing community focus group discussions and household surveys. The schematic structure, shown in Figure 6. consisted of 26 component accounts grouped into five major accounts: production activities. factors of production, institutions, capital, and rest of the world (ROW). The resulting SAM consisted of 16 sub-matrices and six vectors. Each row or column label represents one account. Analysts interpret rows as income or receipts and the columns as expenditures of that particular account. The SAM is a square matrix following the concept that income should equal expenditures. Figures inside the matrix are in monetary values based on nominal peso values in 1998 (US $l=PhP 41.29, average from September to December 1998, the time of the field study). If the study focused on comparison of income between periods, these values would require conversion into real values using a base year. 90 0.30 300002 .005 05 $000.00.. 8.0008600 02.. .0.. 200. ...... 00._s.00.00< . 0030.03092 ,...,... 0.03.0 .. . t . ,... Mi . sum... ll... .. 09:00. 0000 H 30.00.: .100.» . .10.... .A-v. argog .WA’Q nutunaauugf. fifiw umwp U n 0.0000. 0.00: Bvaa’w 39G . 0 . A 3...“. .u o:- 0306—: no 03000000.. 30 .000. n. £00032050 .0.‘0%..0— .0303. a at. an: ....‘w 20.— O: 0,11de “fluid; 3. .... «EJ‘ 020000000 000.00....EA U ..0 .120... Signihfl ......mvwé. . .51.... .. .....ifi 0.0030230. n 3 u .3032 P ads—0.00.2 «m 00.00:. 22.009 n o .300. .30... .00.. . 00 :I n D . 0000.. 3200... 00.30.0000,; :03... N s . . Um... ...... 0.9.93... 003000000 30.0003 _ i no .u 4.... .... < . T... .. . . .. 3m... . .. .... ... 1%.... fix .. . .m. . . . .. ...]. ,...... ”...... . . W1. .0.. Emmu :5 800.00 Aflv not-.9058“; A40 33.3.3.0 ......ux 3:: 90.00:. any 90.300000 0 no: 300 03.20.0034 00 no.0...0090xhfl 00.30030 €3.20 000000000 .30... We 3.0.. ...—000mm ”0050..”000 ...—0:200:34 2.00.030 .0.... ..o .5310 . Eu 010.090.... am: 3 .. ,..Mw..,.......... . .. . .. .. 04...}...04501. 1w 0% fi—O£:».0:.wwi «amu30-:.m=~ :o__a:e_axm~ 30.00 2h... ......,n9.......1.9.. .... ,... .t ...... .... 1. I... . . ....«t...m........... ......__......w.m..k.%h ,...... 05...... .....s...~. .....-ithuim , 905:... ,...: n»...»..u<00:000000 — , 00. 00 00 no. ... u .300 00.0.0.0 0.005 000—0000000 22.000 000.3230. .0 0 0 ...». < tucua 00.0039”. .00 30.00... 002000000 a b o m w n N n nos—.3, 9..-.000: o...uo..uu< .300. £00000Co< :ocoscoi u 9:35:3me 8%.. 25.2. 25.2 25.2 3:8 33 33383 32:8 550 3.5%.: m wag: E3 _ m. 25:52qu own? M 83; 233 8.32%.”. .85 Sod: wig—am .tw< mo£>:o< 5:03.55 3 3 m m x v m m. m m. o. w. m u m. m m. m. m... am. rd n p m U: «NW. D. m m B ...”. I. w m W m. m: «w m W. cm. H w fl W. «sic. s M: u P s m. m m 323» b.5282 oaauohuw< .95me 26828 2: mo < 5:92-939 x55: cogs—55 2.=u< 553605 2283605 86652 853668 62.28% cozmficmweo Eon—056:5 .6 8: $060 m 068; 6:23 ,6 33:25 6:33 83:85 8x32 . Eczemaom 8x32 66:33: 3526531» 6553sz £050 moatucomxm moSEanxm 3: b. u an . . . 66:69.0: 806:3 66:33: SEE—6:5 3» 3282 8a 0.. < 36.53.55 m 3.53233— .Aeaozbm 2362.8 2: 6 m 6.36-65 3:98 55:66:. 6 cog—Ewen .m 29; 99 @353.” 933 33? 34.4? Emu 36.63.: ooo.~ fl m 63 683-683 3393 £4.23 2 $2 32:8 550 633w 833 30.8 3:05: a 835m - - was“; :96: _ m. 26.58% - - EoeonEm own; .m 26.806 30.23. 8.3.2qu :88: Sowmmwm ommfimfivm mEE6m .:w< 8.538,: 55:68: O :o. 8933— mu m 6.63 m 6:an 6_:E:.oo< 5:668:60 .w B m 6:960 62532: 66% W W of 6 “mom w 5:52 6:30 6562 w 6562 8=6> bus—SE ouawouwwaa £906.: mzocowoxm 6:9wu a b e m w 8:56:0an 3588; 266623 2: 6 m a Q .U waEbamv 3:358 22662: 6 33:5 6 2265366 550 .6 2an 100 - - me _ ._ _ meN owed. - - mmvdo 6562 - - - mnmdmv - - mwoé Shem $68.52 338 m *5ng - owed owo,m - _ _ _n_ _ _ mtdm 03.30 .264 :85 N n. 3.0.390 - 36.2 8; .2 3.3: 30.? 0mm, _ 2 owm.wm~._ 3:9: 0:850: 650 M - - www.mwo; vwofimow 3.5m _ m.m ©8533» ooQQflm $635.2 6:3 356m 228355 6 $88 226255 882% mafia; EoEonEm :ocgoaxm map—6‘. Elmo 63 :83 $50 8.5%; 68m own? 320,.— 82.3.:w< 825» E5282 ouawouwwt‘ m2:>.:o< 5:03.05 — gazesm‘m 35825 26838 05 6 “— xcafibsmv 86:65 6 £28”— .h 26% lOl Labor was divided into hired and family labor. This separation proved useful in valuation of traded and non-traded commodities in the community. The value of family labor was not necessarily equal to the opportunity cost of wage labor, but was a residual value of production afier deducting all input costs. This valuation approach uses the assumption that households resort to own-production instead of employing hired labor because the value of output is less than that of hired labor. Thus, there exists an inequality in value of family labor and hired labor. Market imperfections characterized the community thus, shadow prices such as family labor diverged from market wage rates. Capital inputs were divided into man-made and natural capital. The natural capital component differs from the sub-account of natural capital in the account sub-matrix labeled "Capital" (K). This difference is explained later. Here it suffices to mention that natural capital inputs are explicitly market-transacted and produced natural capital used as factor inputs. Other than labor and capital inputs, the household interview revealed a variety of other inputs in small amounts, thus they were lumped into an account labeled "Other domestic inputs" to differentiate inputs that were purchased from outside of the community. The Rest of the World account reflected values of the latter. Component inputs or factors of production define the structure of production. It also typifies a technology employed by households. Obviously, production activities are not similar in component inputs. Some only have natural resources as input while others 102 have both man-made capital and natural capital inputs. In most cases, because production activities are by households, only family labor is involved. The sub-matrix that intersects Factors of Production by itself is a null matrix, because, logically, expenditures by factors of production for itself do not occur. Institutions (Sub-matrices G-J). Table 8 presents the components of the Institution matrix, and its receipts or income for employing its factors of production (Sub-matrix G). In the process of data consolidation, a number of options for classifying institutions emerged. The disaggregation of institutions into components depends on the use of the SAM. The SAM could be used to assess the effect of landlessness, poverty, or lack of basic opportunities on natural resources sustainability. It is also flexible enough to consider environmental concerns. Hence, the purpose dictates the structure as well as content of survey questionnaires to acquire inputs for the matrix. Table 8. Distribution of income from employing factors of production (Sub-matrix G of the schematic structure). Expenditures 2 Factors of Production Aggregate Monetary Values Other Man-made Natural Family Labor Domestic Hired Labor . . Cap1tal C ap1tal Inputs Institutions '2, Smallholder household 42,168,103 650,361 1,090,270 352,334 110,060 '5 3 Landless households 7,434,597 867,605 17,612 140,751 13,261 g People's Organization - 6,094,678 391,994 - - Others not specified 103 In this study. recipients of income from payments to factors of production are households, government and other relevant institutions within or outside a community. Thus, the Institutions account divides into households, people's organization, and government (this part labeled as sub-matrix I is discussed later). Households that compose the major consumption and production actors of communities further sub- divides into holders of small parcels of land (small-holders) and the landless. This classification explores the hypothesis that landholdings directly influence the decision for wage employment (e. g. carpentry or road construction) outside of the community or livelihood activities (e.g. white clay mining) other than agriculture and forestry. A comparison of the magnitude of incomes and expenditures partially supports this hypothesis. A different component appears on the expenditure side for households. A distinction between market-purchased and direct-household consumption expenditures reflects subsistence- or own-production that do not enter conventional accounts. In this study, for instance, direct household consumption of own-production was P 12,618,383 (distributed among small-holder and landless households) or 17% of total production value. These additional components are not covered by traditional accounting approaches. The importance of this disaggregation is emphasized in a later section. People's organization (PO) is not a typical entry in a SAM. It was included for two purposes. First, the government's community-forestry program recognizes the important role of non-govemment or people's organizations on natural resource conservation and economic development. Thus, the SAM includes these people's 104 organizations to evaluate their impact on natural resources and economic performance. Second, the PO appears in order to represent the institutional set-up of the community- based forest management concept. These POs serve as the rule-making institution for common property management. as a conduit for external support of forest management activities such as loans or financial assistance, and as the marketing arm for community outputs. This serves to emphasize that it is very important to develop accounts at the community level rather than simply aggregating all household production. Decisions do not originate solely from the household, but also from the community. This is particularly true when common pool resources exist that in most cases are strong points of political contention. Chapter 6 briefly expounds on this aspect. Not all income or receipts of institutions derive from employing factors of production in community production activities. Households acquire income from wage employment outside of the community; thus, the SAM (Sub-matrix H and J) records these as remittances from external sources. In addition, government welfare programs include subsidies or transfers to a number of residents (Sub-matrix I). Table 9 (Sub- matrices H, I, J) presents various non-factor incomes from outside of the community. Likewise, policy implications for production and consumption require inclusion of Government accounts under institutions to cover taxes. transfers and subsidies that goes into the production (recorded in sub-matrix N), and other institutions (recorded in sub-matrix H). In the SAM, analysts treat government as an exogenous factor that influences endogenous activities. Hence, for purposes of SAM analysis this was grouped together with Rest of the World accounts. 105 wufiwoofi 82mm wmm midwfim 3.28% 8: 32.5 m _ @0me owm.moo.m 00%: me. _ o_ cosaficmwho @0385 8 3:de $22: - msofimaofiascfl a m howfiovdv New. _ 3: wood: 8.23:0: 520::aEm M. 225:3:— ua 0 d .d d s d i G H N N S O I. l. H I n J H w n o 9 m V B G e .I d ... an .d 0 Q. 0 e 1 0 0. 0 W. 1 m m. o m m mmamw mu. ma Wm”... mmm my; mwm a n u. m u wwmwmwm mm wwwgmnmww 61w”. m S w. u 3 .n1 3 m 3 m P w m s w I s o 1 o l W 1 a m M w a w a m a m u p ... u p ,.... mu.. 1 d 1 1. 1 1. .W ml. W m. m. m m. w m. 1 3:95:35 maiztconxm 83920qu 83.; b.3282 o.¢uo..uu< P £060 £22.33: 303:3 mac—0:330; cov_o£_mEm £90m”. gocomoxm 23:30 28:2sz a _ h _ ... _ m w m 3535:9an .5. ._ .I x. £81239 £55355 Amsocowowcov 2 3:593 25 Emacs: .moocfizssm d 2an 106 Capital (Sub-matrix K,L,M). This major account divides into four important components: Savings/Investment, Natural Capital Depreciation, Natural Capital Accumulation, and Human Capital (Table 10). Conventional accounts normally ignore natural and human capitals. The Saving/Investment account may include household savings invested in production activities. Part of production activity outputs (sums up to P 1,298,379 in this study) goes to savings of households (sub-matrix M) and institutional demand for output (sub-matrix C, discussed earlier). These savings constitute the main investment capital for further production activities or for human capital enhancement (M). The natural capital depreciation and accumulation reflect subtractions (harvest/exploitation and damages) and additions (growth and forest expansion), respectively, that result from resource use. Neither natural capital depreciation nor accumulation is a feature of standard national accounts or the SAM. In conventional SAMs, only a portion of natural resources appear as priced inputs (as priced factors of production) or outputs of production, and its depletion (P 8,188,197 in this study) does not appear as a capital consumption component. The conventional approach of accounting does not provide ways of knowing the sustainability of natural resources (timber) stock and flow. Thus, "Natural Resource Depreciation" and "Natural Resource Accumulation" were added to reflect natural capital consumption and outputs of reforestation activities or other resource replenishing activities. This is a way of internalizing natural resources value in the production costs of households and the community. 107 8... 52 802 .956 58:: :oum.=E=ou< 3.95 .8.sz 8 5.8.8500 .SEQU .9332 v m. . 1 . . d 8.. a 5. 8 25 m; amassusémgs a .536 mu .0 H M d H m M m wm am 1 mm mm mmm mmm mmm mmm w 3m .muam U NJ...” WLMul memsxommu mm”. m mm 12 m Wu ”.5... w.0..01 3mm WPm. 9mm 3 n «la. m. M W m m u D. o u D. m m. m m... .m m. .w m 1. W m m... w W. ... 85.33%. megaucoaxm. 8.2.32.5 mo=.a> b.8252 8am€um< 3:25.55 32.5 8.2.8.5.. $2.53 mgozomso: 520....aEm .9260 82.35:. 00 v n W 3.3:...»an— Eaau 58:: w 5.va 8.3.258... .338 3:52 a 02.03.. Rodam 83.8..“ 8.3858 3583532 m. me>mmbco§mo>£ M .936 concave“. meadow 3:0 2 we. L . o .558.qu 5.3.8.9.“... 35.. 21.—mo .03.. @003 .550 . : .... .5 .1 ..S m own? .85“. 23.39:}. 82333.. 8.63.8.5 85.5» b.3232 93953.. _ 8......caonnm a). .1. .v. 5.38-95. .858 582. 28 £23823“ Ea 5.5.853 .958 .832 ..coE.mo>:.\mw=.>am .o. 0...; Natural capital accumulation reports community efforts to replenish natural resource extraction by reforestation or other related activities, and accumulation of stock from natural growth. Information obtained from resources inventories may be treated as supplemental (or satellite) account linked to this account. In the current SAM, this account element records only the reforestation investment by the CBF M project (P422,018). However, based on the stand and stock table for timber resources compiled by three people's organizations, a partial stock assessment is reported in Appendix 32 (Tables 1-3) The inclusion of these components provides help in evaluating the impact of community/household production activities on the stock and flow of natural resources. The section on assessing sustainability ofnatural resources further expounds on this impact evaluation. Human capital is another feature newly explored in SAM development. In conventional SAMs, human capital is treated as an independent vector of account. However, no substantial change occurs if human capital becomes subsumed under Capital as a major account. This records household investment in human capital enhancement. At the community level, this information is vital in assessing expenditures on human capital enhancement. Part of the survey results included records of expenditures of household on education of children (P 1,391,860). In a like manner, the accounts record expenditures by PCs on training and seminars conducted to improve people's organization management capabilities (P 17,500). Table 10 (Sub-matrix L and M) records savings of households and People's Organization as well as investments in human capital. 109 Government (Sub-matrix N3). The sub-matrix N, the intersection of Government and Production Activities (Table 1 l) is a null matrix in the current SAM. Normally, the government receives taxes from production activities (sub-matrix N); however no such data were captured in the household survey, and the C BF M information do not contain explicit payment of taxes to the government. However, the POs record payments to the government in the form of license fees and forest charges from forest exploitation totaling P 1,047,985, recorded in sub-matrix 0. Rest of the World {Sub-matrices P,Qand R). Table II (sub-matrix P) records imports of inputs for production activities and Table 12 (sub-matrix Q) record imports of consumption commodities by households. The five communities are not closed economies, and they are not self-sufficient. A substantial amount of imports and exports to urban centers occur. However, communities are not fully integrated to the market so that not all outputs of production enter the market; a portion is directly consumed. Exports of production outputs and purchase of inputs and consumption goods from outside of the community appear in this account. Any infusion of loans or capital investment other than government from external institutions also appears in this account. The difference between the two accounts appear as Deficit/Surplus. At the current state, imports exceed exports [trade deficit of P 3,557,209. recorded in sub-matrix R] for all five communities. This condition suggests that most consumption commodities are normally purchased from the markets outside the five villages; other than those directly obtained from production output and consumed by household as substitute for traditionally purchased output. 110 «adeqm Swan... 0mm.o.o.m wm..m~o.o 3.9.3.: bonsai: m0:3.0:&xm..80... w 8 ma. muscon h m 03.3... 03.5..mm 010305.050”. e .m. $0.20.. - EoEEBoorm a s d s 0 m d m H I M m H w m «...... .3 mmm mmm mm... wmm Wm mwl wmm. Wm” wmm. me. WHO. w..s. “PP $5... “PW mysw 19 U U 0. N U D. «u... Wu... 3:36:0an. 3:26:35". 8:26:35”. 0.05.5» b.5252 0:30:34: .::0.:E.:m:. 2050 $62030: $0.05. 0.0.9.039. :00.0—...:Em 20:25:. n 00:5..Eomum. 60:36:09.0 ..0 £80. 0:: A0 .0 m00.:.:E-n:m. 20:35:. 3 32:95:00 :0..QE:m:00 ..0 $595 ABOM: 2:03 0:. ..o .m0~. ..:0EEO>oO .N. 0.2:... 80.08.: .8033: .8033 .Em.;w.m .moo.§o.m .3323 .o:.moo.c ..oo.§.mm 3.3630538. 0 ..u m:_m::m.:._0...0n. h w 02.2% 29.3 mwmd 30.3 .mnwvo 020305.050”. o ..w E0EE0>0O m. a. w: m: :0E>.0 a: A...“ .22.... ...... ,_. . ...: a as“... a 2...”... ...m ..3 : m .. ..< .333» m0...>:0< 5:03.005 350:0: 0.:w0..wa< . mun-ZZZEQXM— .E 0:: Z 30:38-05. 3:608:50 5:083:00 0:: 30:. :0 3:005. :0 .30”: 2:03 0:: ..0 .00”. .::0::::0>0O ... 03:... 111 Deficit/Surplus (Vector 7 ). The survey-based social accounting matrix does not easily balance for a number of reasons. In most cases, expenditures recorded do not match with sources of income; exports and imports rarely balance. Thus, a deficit/surplus account was created. For instance, the community received subsidies in various forms: the initiation of the CBFM receives subsidy from the government (P 1,047,985); some households receive welfare financing (P 175,008). On the other hand, the community treats forest rent [calculated as natural depreciation in accounting sense, amounting to P88,188,l97, recorded in (Sub-matrix 7,4)] from natural resource exploitation as part of net income. Thus, natural resource rent less government subsidy is treated as surplus. From the sustainability standpoint, the rent from natural resource exploitation should be treated as depreciation so that government subsidy and depreciation should add up as community deficit. The amount of natural resources depreciation should provide a signal on the amount of natural resource capital accumulation requirement for that particular accounting period. Without natural resources accumulation, the total amount of deficit is equal to government subsidy plus natural capital depreciation. The next chapter discusses the issue of sustainability of natural resources. To aid in impact analysis, SAM entries are classified into endogenous and exogenous accounts. The latter include government and Rest of the World. Changes introduced by exogenous factors shape various endogenous accounts, as discussed in the next section. 112 Uses of the SAM The SAM has two main uses or functions. First, it is used for evaluating the level of economic performance of the community -— or economic profiling. This involves examining each activity's inputs, outputs and income distribution to members or institutions within the community. In rural settings, one outcome of this type of evaluation is a picture of the poverty situation and associated income distribution. Second, the SAM helps in evaluating impacts of exogenous factors such as government and market forces on community economic activities, income distribution, and for this study, natural resources — economic impact assessment. As described in Chapter 3, the SAM provides a snapshot of linkages of various exogenous and endogenous factors affecting consumption and production activities of households. One or two accounts or elements in the matrix, in this case government and rest-of-the-world (ROW) accounts, represent these external factors affecting consumption and production. Any introduced changes of these factors affect natural resources stocks and flows. Hence, natural capital depreciation and accumulation accounts were included as new features of the SAM. Discussion of these SAM functions for the study area follows. Economic Profiling Function of the SAM The SAM serves to characterize and evaluate economic transactions of actors in the community. Evaluation takes on a number of forms. For purposes of this study, 113 evaluation focuses on the impact of consumption and production on natural resources. Four types of evaluation that relate to natural resources are considered: self-sufficiency in production, income distribution, level of integration with the market, and use of factors of production. Results of these evaluation approaches are discussed in turn. First, one evaluates the level of dependence of households or institutions as economic actors on certain production activities. The evaluation outcome reports the degree of dependence of economic actors on a particular production activity or activities. Analysts can use either the base matrix or the average propensity matrix. For example, Table 13 presents measures of average production propensities or percent contribution of production activities to total production in five communities. Agricultural farming represents the largest activity, at 49%, followed by forest-related activities (i.e., CBF M, Forest exploitation, and wood-based fiJCI production). A narrative example of these evaluation types is presented in Appendix C .3. Table [3. Proportion of various production activities to total production. Production Activity Values (Pesos) Proportion Agricultural Farming 35,375,061 49% Forest Exploitation 6,905,719 10% Wage Employment 5,077,387 7% Retail Trading 3,072,002 4% Fisheries 5,884,294 8% Other sources 2,833,365 4% Wood-based fuel 3,582,927 5% CBFM 8,920,866 12% Total 71,651,622 100% 114 A second economic profiling examines income distribution among different household groups (i.e. small-holders, landless, income groups, occupation groups, etc.) and how this impacts natural resources. In this study, the SAM structure aggregated households into small-holder and landless. Table 14 summarizes households sampled and percent of household with lands to cultivate or own agricultural land (small-holder households). Small-holders comprise 72% of total households. The proportion of household with landholdings is one determinant of natural resources exploitation. An example of evaluation is detailed in Appendix C .3. The third evaluation approach identifies major sources of consumption: whether own-production, local-market-purchased, or if the community is a net importer of consumption goods. This type of evaluation determines whether the community is subsistence-type, partially or fully integrated into the market. Simply described, a fully integrated community suggests that consumption goods and production output are marketed; all commodities are transacted in the market, and hence possess market price. Furthermore, trade of production outputs, whether within or outside the community occurs with less significant transaction costs involved. This implies that a considerable portion of natural resource exploitation goes to the market, as shown in Table 15. One notable exception in the SAM for this study showed that 17.6% of total production is household bound, not reflected in the market, hence, not covered by national accounts. This further implies that the five communities are not fully integrated into the market. It is notable also that 21.3% of total production is unmarketed. This figure is close to the estimate made by James (1996), who claimed that direct household consumption is 1/3 of GNP. N _ v 52 mai $0.5m mm 9%.? m _ N EN 38% o Nb— 3. c\oo.o o o\co.oo_ ov ow Bah @— _ mo. Sm $03 «N c\om.mo cw we aflou 3 v2 wvm £66m 2 foods mm ow 83.8% mi N _ m 53 Raw. _ m mm gmdc cc 3 52:589. mm o2 EN KERN m _ o\on.mn ow mm 338m cam $35283 $75823 83:33: 32:55.68 3 mEosomzo: mac—2:3 Eozomsom SEOEEEm Bob 8:538:50 $29.3 cocoa—35m $3595: .881 £58550 n 20:88: mo own—8m o\co~ . . .moEczEEoo o>c 05 .8 89:33 98 29:3 $3 2: E 958.36 2:3 .3 29¢ 116 Table 15. Average propensities for expenditures on consumption for five communities Ex nditum Smallholder households Lan ess households Ofi'riers Institutional AWN“ Expenditure Expendflres Expenditures Expenditures Propensities Market Household Market Household Peo le's Others not Purchases of bound Purchases of bound Or pizatin eci fi ed smallholders production landless roduction gan sp Agn. Farming 38.4% 6.3% 73.7% Forest Exploitation l .6% 1 8% 26.3% g Wage Employment 81% 13.4% § Retail Trading 66% 0.1% '3 Fisheries 7.1% 0.8% 12.4% 5.6% I- ‘- Other sources 11% 5.1% Wood-based fuel 58.1% 81.3% CBFM 80.8% 3 Smallholder households ‘3 Landless households 2 People's Organization 2.2% Others not specified 5.1% 0.0% g Investment/Savings 1.7% 0.6% 4.8% a U Human Capital 0.2% 22 Government 12.0% 0 3 Rest of the world 714% 73.5% Total Expenditures 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% The fourth approach that directly links with natural resources is to evaluate component inputs or factors of production. This focuses on the combination of labor and capital, and whether it is domestic, imported, man-made or natural capital. Labor utilization in rural settings mixes family and hired labor for production activities. Evaluation revolves around how much family labor or hired labor goes into each production activity. Naturally, in rural agriculture, family labor is commonplace; hence, agriculture exhibited the greatest value of family labor. For forestry exploitation, the value of family labor would include of natural resources rent because use of natural capital is not treated as a cost; hence the residual value of production in terms of 117 percentage, including natural capital utilization would sum to 96% (48.85% + 47.18% from Forest Exploitation column in Table 16). In many cases forest production activities are mostly complementary production, employing mostly family labor, to augment income from agriculture. Hired labor is employed mostly in seasonal agricultural cropping. This has policy implications related to providing alternative livelihood activities. Capital utilization, the focus is on how much natural capital goes into production; whether traded or non-traded. Of the total production value, 27% came from natural resources (see Table 13). The intensity of capital utilization reveals the kinds of inputs and factors commonly available or accessible to households in the community. Thus, the outcome provides policy directions related to providing access to natural capital. Other options for evaluation related to factors of production revolve around the objective for constructing the SAM and constituent accounts involved. For instance to evaluate land as factor of production and its depreciation, the analyst should impute value on the land applying valuation techniques such as hedonic pricing, or other non-market valuation techniques. All these types of evaluation help refine SAM construction where data inadequacies can be identified. An evaluation of economic performance of the community over time requires a different approach. The next section discusses these approaches as they relate to decision-making uses of the SAM. 118 moE>co< 5.32605 — nonaguoam $_ ~._ $3.3 $56 $5.2 $m_.o $vm.o $$.~ 283 05.3 30mg EoEEo>00 m 13.96 5:3: can: 8.53532 336 3332 $5.2 $33 as: .5. 822858 .338 3:32 a u mmagumbcogmgfi m £82 $86 $26 .53 3&8 3532 am. ea: $8.“. $88 .258 8.85.5: $om.v $36 $36 $a_ .m $wm.o $mh.~ conni— cBE ~ $mm.wo $3.0 $o~.o $36 $3.— $mm.~ $3.». 3:9: 0:888 .050 $9.3 $3.3 $3.3 $3.3 $3.? $2.60 .883 3.58,.— couosuoa mooBom mafia; Evie—92m 5:86.qu macaw 21.50 3:..— voo? 550 mutogmi ...Som own? 620» ohfi:o.i&< 8:3:— Efiuseeum he 23.—om E anathema...— .=o:o=coa :33 8 55:88 no 882a ho coanoE .2 2an 119 Policy and Management Decision-making Uses of the SAM. The SAM constructed for the five communities, like other SAMs, presents production decisions made by households based on the opportunity set offered for one period — one year. It is a static matrix. This snapshot account does not readily reflect effects of external interventions, which could extend past the l-year period. However, a series of SAM over time can exhibit the long-term trend of structural changes in the rural economy brought about by these interventions. Constructing a SAM multiplier matrix facilitates comparing between periods. Prior to constructing the multiplier matrix, the SAM was divided into endogenous and exogenous accounts (Taylor and Adelman, 1996; Pyatt and Round, 1985). In generalized format: Y= Ag 1; + x (1) Where: Y = vector of total income or receipts A Y = vector of total expenditures (representing column totals in the SAM) A5 = square matrix of endogenous average expenditure propensities for each account x = vector of exogenous injections (i.e. government, ROW, etc) 120 The AE it represents the endogenous component of the matrix. Since, Receipts equal Expenditures, therefore, Y = 1; Hence, simplifying Y yields: Y = (I - Aer'x (2) So that, M: = (I - Ag)" (3) Where: ME = is matrix of Leontief-type multiplier for endogenous accounts 1 = is an identity matrix Based on the generalized form, a schematic presentation of the SAM constructed for the five communities is shown in Appendix C .1 Table 22. Using this schematic framework, the Ag, (1 - A5), and M; were computed. The A5 was computed by dividing each account element by its corresponding expenditures (column) total, and M; is obtained by matrix inversion. Appendix C.1 Table 23 shows the AE and Appendix C .1 Table 24 presents the ME and exogenous multipliers (GE). Table 17 provides a summary of endogenous, ME, and exogenous multipliers, GE. The next section provides interpretations of these multipliers. 121 o: o m3 o 3:69: EEEEMEO do: 3050 @038; 9:53 oo 33:03A— omno ammo onmo in... who o 25>) 2: ..o and m woo o So 3 ~ooo mooo Nooo 3055950 933 he menu—.95...— .235 =2:an 33.5 b.3232 u.auu._uu< ooo _ ooo _ ooo _ ooo _ ooo _ ooo ~ ooo _ ooo _ Eoobam Kw o wmo o oo. o omo o £0 0 nmo o co». o ".mo o 3359:2er owm o :o o oom o to o 3.3 o woo o wow o 36 o 253 05.6 $3. m m 2.. o _oo o woo o moo o Moo 0 ooo o ooo o o .o o EoEEoSO mud Egon... mnocowoxm m. omwo Zoo o2 o mvoo :oo Eoo a_mo onoo Eafiu .. fl woo o 21o moo_ wmm. _ of _ mm”, _ o: 3 wow _ . n qua 3o. mo_ o 30 _ 31m _ _N_ _ mom _ 0:. o .mm _ 5.532; .3 :23... N w. in m w: _ 03. o o: _ mmm _ MN... _ 31m _ .3. _ musizu< zososnoi _ :ozosnoa EoEonEm cosflafizm WEEE 2%: Ed 309.5 mouaom 550 .3555 main; :5“; was? $20... 83.3:3... mo_:>:o< “522605 335.) b.5252 oiueuuw< w u .1 k £23238 .mO .msocomoxo 98 £2 .msocomocco no bee—cam .2 03.; 122 [23 - - ooo._ ooo. _ ooo. _ ooo. _ 39.3w 2 to ES 83 32 293235 a $2. cameo - need 283 250.8% m m memo mid - wvoo 8055300 . m 388... maocowoxm m. 03.5 03.. 89. woo; REED w v. - - - mimm moo; - Sad 823.5:— n w... - - - m2... v3.— - Ewo 55305.8 328“— ~ m. - - - mom..— nhNN - owe; 8353‘. 85255 — H mg a mu m M m A 3:95 ozszano< 5.360300 .m ..u. m o m . . .5.an 255635 m. w. m J m 5:5: .556 . s n m m .8382 3532 1 r u an 398m maoaoxm 3:30 mos—.5 523—: 8a 9.. < n v «Ragga ...—Sagan 8:53:03”.— uoscccoo. . £2322: .mO .mzocowoxo can £2 .msocowonco no 3885 .2 03.; Interpretation of the Matrix Multipliers, M E Exogenous accounts in the SAM link the community to various external factors (see Figure 1) that change over time. Market prices of exports or imports affect household production; savings/investment and government actions in the form of policy change, institutional arrangements or regulation affect opportunity set for consumption and/or production; external remittances or donations increase incomes of households. Thus, any income effect changes household expenditure/consumption decisions, and subsequently production decisions. Conceptually, various linkages can explain the effects. Exogenous impacts are transmitted to production activities, factors of production, whether natural or man-made. then to receipts by institutions from value added in production. Part of the income by institutions is spent on consumption goods or expenditures by institutions such as small- holder or landless households that are either imported or domestically purchased; thus, part of the production impacts leaks to outside of the community. A change introduced by exogenous factors can be positive or negative (Pyatt and Round, 1985). For each one unit (peso) of exogenous introductions into any account, say the upper leftmost row and column (Table 15), means that the ultimate amount for agriculture production will be increased (decreased) by P 1.441, an increase (decrease) of P 0.441 of such production. The total value of agriculture production including the values of inputs is: 124 l*M= 1,441+ 1.351 + 1.408 +0.076=4.28 In a similar way. restriction on forest exploitation (row 1. column 2) can be expressed as: -1*M = -1.243 - 0.719 - 0.749 - 0.519 = -3.23 A l-unit value reduction in forest exploitation will ultimately reduce overall forestry production activity by P -3.23 including reduction in the employment of factors of production previously used for such purposes. An application of this type of analysis related to external intervention relative to sustaining natural resources is discussed in a later section. It is important at this point to place qualifying interpretations of the multipliers. First, the increases/decreases of values initiated by the original introduction occur because of direct, indirect, and induced effects as the reactions go around the linkages of various accounts; they are not instantaneous impacts. Decomposition of such effects were discussed by a number of studies but not covered by this study. Second, it is important to note that these multipliers assume that prices are fixed. and income elasticity is unity, even with the introduction of exogenous changes. It is likely that prices may change as a result of exogenous changes. Changes in prices may motivate households to shifi production activities. Therefore, prices determine the opportunity set workable for households. Any exogenous policy intervention should look at where the multiplier effects start and how they affect endogenous accounts. For instance, the CBF M seem to be isolated from other sectors of the community because of its limited linkage. This has implications on income distribution pattern of the CBFM program on the community. This type of analysis is possible by decomposing the ME so that indirect and induced effects are determined. Alternative approaches emerged from examining the SAM. One approach looks at the value of family labor for each production activity. The higher absolute value of family labor would suggest greater emphasis on that particular production activity in the next period. In Table 16, wage employment provided the highest value of family labor followed by agriculture. Besides agriculture production, the next best supplemental activity for households will be forest exploitation, other than wage employment. It must be noted that family labor in forestry, in reality, includes rent value of natural resources used in production. Households do not calculate rent of natural resources because they treat it as free factor of production. Another alternative approach is to regress family labor with total production, hired labor, domestic and imported inputs, and capital inputs. This can be done for relevant production activities such as agriculture, forestry, retail trading, fisheries and others. The parameter to assess will be the size of coefficient of 'total production' variable. The 'total production' with the highest coefficient will be the most likely 126 production activity that farmers would shift to or concentrate in addition to other production activities. Obviously, forest production activity will be part of that opportunity set that households undertake. Thus, natural resource depreciation is always an account to look closely in any rural production accounts. In summary, components of the SAM can be tailored to the need of actors for such information. The types of evaluation will depend on the focus of decision making. Thus, analysts develop the SAM based on situational needs. Entries in the SAM, are consolidated and measured in monetary terms. Values are based on actual transactions. Sustainability of Natural Resources Recorded in the SAM The third component of framework development (objective #2 of this study) involved establishing a link between natural resources recorded in the SAM and the stock and flow of timber resources; this provides a picture of sustainability of timber resources used in economic activities. lnfonnation from the SAM is used to simulate changes in timber resources stock and flow over time — a basis for examining resource depletion/accumulation. Ideally, the SAM pictures a general equilibrium in the village that equates supply and demand or production sustains consumption. If this equality holds over time, the community is self-sufficient in production. A corollary would be that the combination of man-made and natural capital sustains the consumption by households. Natural resources 127 accumulation constantly equals or exceeds depreciation; hence, the community is maintaining its natural resource productivity. Consequently, its consumption pattern for natural resources is sustainable. However, communities are not closed economies because certain consumption needs are not available within, and households export to markets outside the community. The combination of exogenous and endogenous factors influence exploitation of natural resources, beyond the minimum needed within the community. Proof of sustainability of natural resources lies on the stock and flow patterns as affected by changes of various exogenous and endogenous factors. The next section presents results of modeling natural resources stock and flow helpful for impact assessment. Modeling Natural Resource Exploitation Identifying indicators of sustainability requires modeling interactions of human exploitation (recorded in the SAM) and the natural resources system. Two aspects important in the development of a model of natural resources exploitation are the magnitude of demand (and its rate of increase) and the stock and flow of resources over time. The SAM indicates current levels of consumption (treated as demand). Modeling based on a resource assessment or inventory provides information on the stock of resources. 128 The forest resources are part of renewable, dynamic system with its varied uses and products exploited by the community. Forests are depletable beyond a certain threshold of exploitation (and impacts are seen only over a longer period). Those who exploit resources and decision-makers at the community level do not know this threshold. Thus, a rational decision considering incomplete information is to simulate natural resource conditions over time as it is affected by human exploitation. The objective of modeling was to simulate the impact of resource exploitation by the community, specifically for timber resources. A variety of tools could be used to create and run the simulation. A simple approach briefly presented in Chapter 3 was spreadsheet simulation using Microsoft Excel. The approach confines simulation to timber resources using the framework applied by delos Angeles et al. (1995) for the Philippine second growth forests. Harvesting, natural damages and random fire occurrences reduce the beginning stock, measured in cubic-meters, of timber over a 25- year period. The simulation evaluated three harvesting (exploitation) scenarios based on current demand by the community. The first harvest scenario considered a harvest of 74 hectares per year proposed by the CBF M . The second harvest scenario harvested based on current growth per year. The third harvest scenario, otherwise called the local minimum wood requirement (reflected in the SAM), harvested 2,652 cubic meters per year (16 hectares harvested per year). Figure 7 shows the stock trend based on these harvest scenarios. This Figure 7 scenarios assume a single fire occurrence over 25 years, 129 (at the let year) that causes a 5.2% loss (damage) to the existing stand (based on national average reported by AIFM for the Philippines - AIFM, 1996). Opening Stock of Timber ‘ —-a"II““ + Harvest = Growth —I— Proposed Harvest ___ . ____ L +Min Wood Req. Volume of Timber, cu m . 1 l 1 i 1 i r V r T‘] '- (V) In I‘- O '- (‘O In h- 0'0 '- ("a v- v- v- v- v- 0] N In 0.] Years Figure 7. Simulation of the effect of three harvest scenarios on natural resources stock. Appendix C.5 Table 31 summarizes series of simulation with varying number of fire occurrences. Appendix C .5 Table 32 summarizes a series of simulations to determine the level of harvest that will make the ending stock of timber to be not significantly different from the beginning stock — a procedure to evaluate maintaining the productive stand. The sustainable harvest at varying fire occurrences was 12 hectares per year, with an average of 165 cu m harvest per hectare (average of harvest per hectare by three POs) producing 1968 cubic meters. It is worth noting that the minimum wood requirement required a harvest of 16 hectares per year. The policy implications means that harvest must be regulated or wood consumption must be reduced. The impact of this change on the community can be analyzed using SAM multipliers (discussed later). This 130 further implies that households may choose to recover lost income by switching to other livelihood sources. In the analysis of the five communities’ proposed harvest, timber will be declining at a rapid rate, exceeding the growth rate of existing stands and new growths. Pending more detailed analysis this indicates that timber resources will be declining continuously unless (I) the communities decide to reduce harvest to the level of the in- growth, or (2) the government regulates natural resources exploitation through policy actions such as regulation or changing land tenure agreements, or (3) the communities institute arrangements through group contracting to control timber exploitation (Figure 1 provides alternatives for external interventions on community economic activities). Impacts of these approaches on the SAM are discussed in the next section. Evaluating SAM Changes Using Multipliers The section on interpreting multipliers demonstrated the usefulness of SAM multipliers in evaluating impacts of exogenous intervention on the community economic system. Two types of exogenous interventions are examined: regulating timber exploitation activities so that it is sustainable and promoting shifis to other production activities. 131 SA M, Simulation of Natural Resources and Multiplier Analysis The SAM records the value of exploitation of timber resources (as proxy for natural resources). This value was transformed to a volume measure for use in natural resources simulation. Different demand scenarios were simulated. If the outcome of the simulation for a demand scenario proves unsustainable, as the case of the CBF M proposed harvest, a recommended policy option is to reduce harvest by government regulation and promote shifts to other activities. Returning to the SAM multiplier analysis, an analyst can evaluate the impact of such reduction on levels of production and income distribution. An illustrative example. below, suffices to demonstrate the use of multiplier matrix. The wood requirement of the community was 2.535 cubic meters of timber equivalent to 16 (2 15.34) hectares harvested of the second growth forest. Previous analysis showed that such a harvest level causes the stock to decline by 0.07% average annually over a 25-year period. A rational decision would be government regulation or self-regulation by monitoring and controlling community exploitation, or to encourage use of other non-timber products for consumption. Nonetheless, harvest of timber should be reduced to 2,209 cubic meters, equivalent to 12 hectares of second growth forest. The total value of timber harvest reduction is P2,349,446. This value, if intervention would be introduced, corresponds to a reducing total production of the community. Using multiplier analysis, the actual value reduction considering direct, indirect and induced effects amounts to P 10,675,060. 132 Since the underlying objective is to sustain the well-being of households/ community, the reduction in income from one production activity must be translated to increase in other activities. Thus, the subsequent SAM analysis can illustrate increases in production in other sectors of the household/community economy to offset declines in forest exploitation. Table 18 shows a possible scenario resulting from shifts in production activities. This shows proportionate increases in all other activities with the decline in forest production (assuming minimal constraint in production shifts). Table 18. Change in production distribution resulting from external intervention. Projected Production Activity Values (Pesos) Production Difference Inc/ Dec % Chage (PesosL Agricultural Farming 35,375,061 41,568,111 6,193,050 Increase 18% Forest Exploitation 6,905,719 3,651,683 (3,254,036) Decrease 47% Wage Employment 5,077,387 5,966,276 888,889 Increase 18% Retail Trading 3,072,002 3,609,812 537,810 Increase 18% Fisheries 5,884,294 6,914,447 1,030,153 Increase 18% Other sources 2,833,365 3,329,397 496,032 Increase 18% Wood-based fuel 3,582,927 1,894,620 (1,688,307) Decrease 47% CBFM 8,920,866 4,717,275 (4,203,590) Decrease 47% Total 71,651,622 71,651,622 This process completes the linkage of SAM, simulation of natural resources, and multiplier analysis. This completes a framework of natural resource accounts at the community level. Alternative policy options to reduce harvest of timber resources include: Institutional arrangements may include: - Active management and control spearheaded by the PO; - Community reforestation to expand or accumulate natural capital; and - Self-regulation or institute internal protection measures. 133 Govemment-supported measures or intervention: Regulate harvest by reducing the annual allowable cut; Provide incentives for reforestation or forest expansion; Provide security of tenure for common-property management; and Provide incentive for shifting to other livelihood activities. Market measures include: - Reduce price of timber/wood substitutes for construction, energy, and other uses; and - Increased prices of agricultural or non-timber forest products to promote shifts to non-timber based livelihood. These measures can be evaluated by quantifying and monetizing their effects in order to be comparable with other measures. A cost-benefit analysis framework would fit into this evaluation process. In summary, this chapter presented results of the development of the SAM. multipliers and simulation of natural resources. Development of the SAM framework useful for decision- and policy-making involved three aspects. The first aspect concerns determining the most appropriate structure of accounts that captures economic activities in the community. Identifying and structuring of account elements are dependent on the goals of SAM development, economic conditions, and available data. It is important to transform data into monetary units so that account elements are comparable, and for 134 potentially linking to national accounts. The resulting SAM provides various options for socio-economic assessment and natural resources accounting. The second aspect concerns linking SAM to natural resources exploitation such as timber resources. The SAM records the order of magnitude of timber resources exploitation for one period — it is a static framework. Comparing this exploitation with the stock and flow of timber presents a dynamic picture of the sustainability of the latter. Dynamic information is rarely available; thus. analysts resort to modeling natural resources. Hence, a simulation model can be developed to capture the link between community production activities natural resource stock and flow. In this study, a spreadsheet simulation was used to model harvest demand and natural stock and flow. At current/proposed harvest rates, timber stocks will be declining and will not be sustainable. The third aspect concerns evaluating the impact of external intervention in order to sustain natural resource stock and flow. This required conducting a SAM multiplier analysis. The process involved segregating endogenous and exogenous accounts in the SAM and deriving the average expenditure propensities. From these averages a Leontief- type multiplier was developed. A multiplier measures the impact of a l-unit increase in exogenous intervention on the endogenous accounts of the SAM. The SAM, simulation and multiplier analysis all compose the overall framework of natural resource accounting at the community level that is helpful not only for 135 economic profiling but decision-making as well. A number of other concerns were observed in the process of developing the accounting framework at the community level. These concerns are further discussed in the next chapter. Further, the next chapter summarizes this whole study and provides further avenues for improving accounting framework development. 136 CHAPTER 6 SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS This study consisted of three parts. The first part, Chapters 1 and 2, outlined the research problem and objectives and reviewed literature on natural resource accounting. The second part, Chapters 3 and 4, described the conceptual basis and empirical methods for developing a framework for community-based natural resource accounting focusing primarily on household activities. This included developing a method of data collection. The third part included Chapter 5, which presented data analysis and results, and Chapter 6 which summarizes results and provides policy recommendations. Summary The objectives of this study are to develop natural resources accounting framework applicable at the community or village level and to link this accounting system to sustainability of stock and flow of natural resources. The first objective focused on incorporating natural resources exploitation into an accounts system in rural communities, with the intent to link to a broader system of national accounts. The underlying reason was to correct measures of economic growth that ignores the contribution of natural resources. The second objective focused on decision-makers at the local level and policy makers at the broader scale — how to deal with information on impacts of production and consumption on natural resources. 137 The focus on rural households and communities emphasized the fact that this sector of the economy subsists or depends on natural resources other than their agriculture production. This study developed an account framework at the local level (village or community) that captures both marketed and non-market-transacted consumption and production output of households, particularly those related to natural I'CSOUI'CCS. Account framework development began with a review of a number of accounting systems developed for industrialized and developing countries, with the end in view of defining an account system useful at the community level. Most of the frameworks reviewed were macro in scale involving aggregates at the national level, and they were not linked to local accounts. Several frameworks incorporated both environmental and natural resource accounts, but sparsely covered household transactions or activities. Typically, household transactions include both market and non-market goods. However, this study focused only on natural resource commodities, and did not include non-market goods. Measurement and valuation of these goods remains a target for future work. The conceptual framework, discussed in Chapter 3, introduced the Social Accounting Matrix in order to capture household consumption and production activities in rural communities. The SAM records income and expenditures from production activities. Factors of production involve mostly family labor and indigenous capital such as non-produced natural resources capital. However, internal and external factors influence these economic activities. These internal factors include household 138 characteristics (mostly household demographics, labor composition, and assets), consumption patterns, and production capacities. External factors include government and market forces that influence household consumption and production activities. For instance, government policies and regulations on use of natural resources can reduce or expand production activities, while market forces such as price levels and costs of commodity transactions affect household decisions to trade or directly consume output. Hence, these influencing factors determine the magnitude of resources transacted in the market and thus, recorded in conventional accounts. The SAM provides a snapshot of these transactions that can aid policy and decision makers in introducing interventions necessary to improve well-being in the community. A temporally extended analysis that determines the impact of consumption and production patterns resulting from activity linkages provides a picture of natural resource sustainability. Developing the SAM required collecting income, consumption and production data at the household level in the community (Chapter 4). The study covered a cluster of 5 out of 10 communities surrounding the Bicol National Park. All consolidated, the five communities comprised 1,493 households. A sample of 20% of households was obtained using stratified-proportional sampling. All information from the 20% sample from each sub-community within a community was expanded and consolidated to one SAM covering all communities sampled. The survey method consisted of three stages: community entry and initial interactions, focus group discussion, and finally the household survey using a 139 questionnaire designed for face-to-face interviews. The first two stages served to conceptually diagram the economic structure of the community and refine the structure of the survey questionnaire. The third stage was the main source of income, consumption and production data recorded in the SAM. Obtaining auxiliary information such as stock of natural resources in second- growth forest required other methods of collection. Information on the stock and flow of natural resources required resource inventory and growth-and-yield modeling that required the same amount of effort as the survey. Hence, the stand and stock tables developed by three POs of the community-based management program of the DENR were used as proxies for modeling natural resources sustainability. Future studies related to SAM development could expand to incorporate a resources inventory including non- timber resources. Thus far, the timber resource model suffices for this study. Chapter 5 summarized results of the SAM development. Questionnaire responses required careful encoding, structured storage, cleaning, and consolidation. The consolidated survey recorded fifty-one different livelihood activities. Eight were agriculture related, twelve were forestry activities and the rest of the 31 non-land-based activities were categorized into fisheries, retail trading and wage employment. The SAM model aggregated these 51 livelihood activities into six major production activities namely: agriculture, forestry, wage employment, retail trading, fisheries, wood fuel and community-based forest management (CBF M). The Production Activities sub-matrix disaggregated forest activities such as fuelwood production and CBFM activities for 140 purposes of evaluating the impact of these activities on natural resources. The SAM also classified households into landholders and landless in order to determine income distribution issues as well as its significance in evaluating natural resource exploitation. The constructed SAM in this study resembled a conventional SAM except that the former explicitly identifies natural capital accounts and household-bound production outputs, and mainly based on household information. Natural capital depreciation and accumulation accounts appeared as components of the Capital accounts, while household-bound output accounts went into, but were distinguished from, household expenditures on production outputs. The inclusion of natural resource depreciation/accumulation and household-bound production outputs embodies two purposes. One purpose was the need to determine the proportion of natural resource exploitation that remains unrecorded in conventional accounts. The other purpose was to evaluate the impact of household-bound production and consumption on sustainability of natural resources. The addition of natural resources, not traditionally marketed, into the SAM must conform to measurement standards and valuation. Hence, all natural resources added to the SAM were converted into monetary terms using market values (Chapter 4). The SAM structure, with its components identified, its elements measured and valued uniformly, allows a number of evaluation fimctions. Broadly, these functions are economic profiling and impact evaluation. Economic profiling focused on such issues as 141 production-activity dependence, income distribution among types of households (i.e., among small-holders and landless — the latter comprise 25% of total population in 5 communities) and for dominant sources of consumption goods (i.e. import dependence, market-purchased, man-made or natural). In addition, profiling can be used to evaluate if the community is subsistence-type or integrated into the market, and types of capital inputs used; whether it is man-made or natural capital. The snapshot model of the SAM is well suited to these evaluation needs. The structure of the SAM largely determines the form of evaluation. The impact evaluation makes use of the direct and indirect linkages between consumption, production activities and capital resources (man-made or natural), to predict the outcomes of the latter over a longer planning horizon. These linkages transmit changes to all account elements. These changes are determined through a multiplier analysis by converting the SAM into multiplier matrix. Any introduction or changes in exogenous (external) factors are assessed for their economic impacts on communities through these multipliers. Undertaking impact evaluation required simulating timber stock and flow. The focus for this study was on timber resources in order to demonstrate the usefulness of the SAM framework for these types of impact evaluation. Evaluation for other resources is constrained by unavailability of stock and flow information that can be obtained only through growth and yield modeling. inventory or sampling. 142 The timber stock and flow model adopted from the delos Angeles et a1 (1991) framework evaluates yearly opening and closing stocks of timber as they are affected by natural and man-made harvests and reductions. The net change in stock, closing, and opening stocks at every period provides a picture of the sustainability of timber resources over the long-term planning horizon. Results of the simulation, considering random (hence stochastic) fire and natural mortality, showed that the proposed harvest volume every year by the POs rapidly depletes timber resources over the 25-year planning model. On the other hand, the sustainable harvest suggests harvesting equivalent to the average annual growth of the existing stand, resulting to positive net growth. Therefore, policy intervention requires regulating harvest per hectare or reducing area harvested per year. The report of the simulation results provides local-level decision-makers some potential impact information on current exploitation of natural resources. In the long-run, the impact of exploitation by the community on natural resources depends on its rate of harvest and natural resource regeneration capacity. Three harvest options were evaluated: (1) harvest based on total wood requirement, (2) harvest based on preferred (proposed) harvest of 74 hectares per year, and (3) harvest based on current annual growth. If harvest (option 2) exceeds current annual growth, the rate of depreciation of natural resources is 4.21% in each period. If the harvest equals current annual growth, the rate of depreciation is 0.32%. If harvest depends on current wood requirement, the stock of timber resources still shows annual depreciation of 0.07%. The 143 resulting depreciation despite harvest at or below annual growth can be attributed to fire damage (5.2% damage to existing timber stock) that occurred at the let year, natural mortality and harvest damages introduced in the simulation. Therefore, critical indicators of sustainability of natural resources include harvest levels, non-harvest reduction factors such as natural mortality, forest fire, and current annual growth or growth and yield of existing stock. Thus, other than the level of harvest, forest fire is a dominant factor in the depreciation of timber stock. Results from analysis of SAM showed that 21.3% of community output was non- market transacted and natural resource depreciation at current wood production/ consumption was 0.07% annual average over 25 years. However, a proposed harvest of 74 hectares annually would cause a 4.21% annual average depreciation over the same period. Production activities in five communities consisted of 27.09% natural resources while non-marketed consumption consisted of 5.79% forest (natural) resources. In the simple spreadsheet simulation, only the timber component of natural resources was modeled, making an assumption that all other system resources remains constant. In real world situation, this is not the case. Thus, a simulation model that takes other forest system resources and linkages is proposed. Conclusion In conclusion, the Social Accounting Matrix framework captured economic transactions (consumption and production activities) in rural communities including both 144 man-made (produced) and natural (non-produced) capital. Incorporating account elements for natural resource depreciation/accumulation and non-marketed outputs distinctly shows, and allows evaluation of, impacts of economic activities on the stock and flow of natural resources. In addition, the use of simulation and multiplier analysis provides a way of linking natural resources accounts with socio-economic evaluation. Thus, the accounting framework is useful for decision-making at the community level. The SAM brought out three important issues. First, it showed that at least 21.3% of consumption and production are non-market-transacted; either directly consumed by household otherwise absorbed in destinations other than markets. Second, the current level of exploitation of natural resources reduces existing stock of natural resources. Increasing current level of exploitation will progressively increase the rate of depreciation. Third, because of the nature of access to resources (land tenure), rural households shift from one production activity to another, thus, exploitation of natural resources is dynamically linked with other livelihood activities. The constructed SAM is a flexible framework. It can accommodate other activities that may occur in the future or those not captured by the survey. The number of activities can be expanded, disaggregated, or further fine-tuned in order to suit decision- making and policy needs. The matrix can be revised to include activities relevant for policy analysis. For example, future activities such as community reforestation can be added to the list of activities. Another activity that concerns government is timber poaching or illegal logging activities. Other activities related to environmental concerns, 145 such as establishment of eco-tourism sites, within the Bicol National Park may be incorporated into the SAM with minor modifications. It may entail adding another row or column, or even a major account on environmental concerns. The simulation model can incorporate linkage accounts that pertain to potential soil erosion and off-site sedimentation. What the SAM accomplished that other account systems did not, was the option to internalize the value of natural resources into the production technology of the household. The value of exploitation of natural resources was added as a cost via depreciation value. This approach effectively incorporates values of natural capital into the account system. Hence, the issue of treating the natural resource accounts as a satellite account at the community level is no longer necessary. The next step in the process is to link community accounts into regional or national accounts. This may require additional work of developing an aggregate linkage accounts with regional and national level. This initial attempt at developing a SAM at the village level certainly has room for expansion. At this early stage, it is already evident that the matrix has a number of evaluative uses for natural resources and for demographic and social questions. Policy Implications At the outset, natural resource accounts attempt to resolve deficiencies of commonly used measures of growth such as GDP and National Income by including 146 natural resources into conventional accounts. Such efforts are not straightforward additions because the issue of commonality of measures and valuation. Conventional accounts include only market-transacted economic outputs, whereas a large part of natural resources exploitation does not enter traditional markets. Natural resource exploitation in rural communities remains unrecorded despite the growing dependence of a considerable portion of developing country population on such resources. Following that reasoning, equally large household production outputs are directly consumed that does not enter mainstream economic transactions. Aggregate natural resource accounting systems do not capture these rural economic transactions. Thus, a framework of natural accounting at the community level is recommended. This study arrived at a simple framework that relates or links household-bound production outputs with mainstream economic accounts. The framework emanated from a concept of household well-being that maximizes consumption of outputs from various production activities and market transactions. Market-transactions of household partially represent total consumption because household-bound goods are not reflected. In many cases, household market transactions depended upon money income from various production activities, taking into account that part of own-production are consumed at the household level. Accordingly, natural resource exploitation reflected in conventional accounts is incomplete, as this study showed. The accounting framework makes use of the SAM structure in order to reflect natural resources as factors of production employed by rural households or the 147 community. The SAM proved useful for a number of evaluation needs relating to natural resource exploitation, whether static or dynamic. The level of dependence, income-effect, level of market integration, and intensity of factor use can all be assessed from the SAM. Understanding all the capabilities makes the SAM a flexible tool for accommodating policy analysis needs. Thus, the SAM structure has important policy considerations. Policy considerations emanating from the SAM can be divided into three classes: monitoring and evaluation, resource sustainability, and formulating policy or market interventions. The SAM analysis showed that conventional accounts potentially record only 78% of actual production that uses natural resources. What are the implications of these? The simplest interpretation means that rural communities, as expected, are not fully integrated into the market system. As such, subsistence production is considerable, and communities rely substantially on natural resources to substitute for commodities that they are unable to purchase in the market because of income constraints. The SAM becomes a useful alternative account system that provides clues and early warning of effects on natural resources exploitation. Policy interventions become crucial if overexploitation is evident. Alternative courses of action revolve around sustaining the resource base in the face of continued exploitation. A number of policy-related questions that can guide courses of action follow: I48 o If viewed as useful, who will develop the SAM? If the SAM would be useful at the community level, decision-makers at the community must devise a plan for data collection and construction of the SAM. The frequency of collection, steps involved, type of data, number and type of sampling to employ will depend on the analysis required by the community. Implementing these activities depends on the motivation for doing so. Unless members of the community see the importance of natural resource accounting, the SAM remains simply a theoretical construct. The framework provides a mechanism for communities to know the status of their resources. A yearly accounting will provide information on the trend of various indicators such as harvest, consumption, household-bound goods, and those that integrate into the market. If the community stakeholders are convinced about the issue of sustainability, critical indicators will be important to them. The SAM can be structured in a way that community decision-makers can readily extract information about the indicators of resource sustainability. o Is the SAM helpful in identifying market and policy failures at the community level? 149 The SAM provides a static picture of the economic situation in the community. In order to evaluate trends of economic performance, such a matrix must be renewed at pre—determined intervals. The interval may be dictated by implementation of certain projects or programs, so the SAM could be constructed at the start and end of program implementation. Ideally, yearly data collection provides adequate decision-making information to monitoring progress of community programs. Disaggregating account elements in the SAM (i.e., factors of production and their sources - natural, man-made, or imports - capital accounts, and institutional recipients and such as households or income groups) would provide clues on the policy or market failures. In the factors of production accounts, propensity to use family labor or natural capital from open-access resources demonstrate inequality of market wage rates and rents for use of natural capital, respectively. In capital accounts, high propensity to use natural capital versus man-made capital exhibits propensity to capture natural resources rent. A high degree of dependence by landless households on natural resources would suggest the same. These situations can be shown in the SAM depending on how it is structured. Will households shift to market commodities if it increased their income or if prices of market commodities were subsidized? The answer to this question depends upon how the community would respond to the market, the opportunity costs that households face, and the price trend of natural resource over time. An increasing demand price for natural resources will increase exploitation, possibly beyond recovery as prices rise. It was shown in the SAM that higher income households have relatively higher proportion of market purchases. If this is statistically significant remains to be analyzed. 0 Does land tenure or ownership have an impact on the exploitation of natural resources? This question arises because of the transfer of management of second- growth forest to community organizations. The SAM reported that landless households, relative to small-holder households, have higher natural resource consumption not transacted in the market. This suggests a lack of opportunities for landless households, giving them more incentive to access public lands for “free resources.” Transfer of management as common pool resource potentially encourages self-regulation of these "free access." 0 How can non-marketed natural resource exploitation be incorporated into broader accounts such as the regional or national accounts? If it is possible to 151 incorporate, should the conventional accounts be revised upward as a result of inclusion of household-bound production outputs? Rural communities' exploitation of natural resources is systematically ignored in regional and national accounts. These accounts reflect mostly transactions by business establishments such as logging companies, mills and integrators, and government forestry activities. SAMs developed for rural communities could be incorporated in a number of ways. One approach would create a separate rural community sector in the listing of establishments. Another approach is to disaggregate forestry accounts and include rural household natural resources exploitation activities or household production activities. These policy-related questions could be subject of subsequent studies related to SAM development at the community level. They could not be covered by this study due to some limitations listed in the next section. Limitations The survey conducted only partially contributed to the development of a full SAM because it was confined to households. SAM construction often includes transactions by other institutions (e.g., NGOs, churches etc.) government employment and linkages between communities. According to Taylor and Adelman (1996), these data need required extension of data collection to a minimum of one year. 152 In natural resources modeling or simulation, efforts were focused on timber resources. As explained in Chapter 4, assessment of non-timber forest resources requires considerable amount of time — more than possible with the survey conducted. Further. lacking empirical data on fire damages, natural mortality, growth and yield functions, a method referred to as "data transfer" was employed. It simply means that research results from areas other than the study sites were used as parameters in the simulation. These parameters may not reflect real conditions of the research site so caution must be exercised in viewing the depletion results. But the overexploitation concern has been raised. The SAM, like other input-output models, has several inherent limitations. First, relationships among production, factors and income distribution are linear — proportionate relationships. This construction does not take into consideration dynamic changes in price and income elasticities. Second, the SAM is a static framework. All exogenous injections cycle through the rounds of impact based on the original base matrix, assuming no changes over time. Third, the resulting matrix of multipliers is what developers called "accounting multipliers" as opposed to fixed price multipliers. The difference between the two lies in the assumption for the former that income elasticity is constant — the multiplier was derived from average propensities for expenditure rather than the marginal propensities for expenditures. Finally, the household survey instrument, despite its length, could not cover time and motion studies in order to calculate household time and labor used for their 153 production activities. The bulk of the household survey focused on consumption, production and demographic characteristics. Thus, continuance of similar types of studies needs to re-evaluate the structure of the questionnaire. Hence, this study recommends a number of revisions for future studies. Recommendations for Future Studies Based on the experiences of conducting this study, the following suggestions target improvement of future studies: 1. Expand SAM construction by incorporating activities of institutions other than household production and consumption. This will include government institutions, details of small- and medium- scale industries, and more details on external transactions of the community; Continue the study in the same area by including a resources assessment or inventory; Focus more on linkages between communities, i.e., inter-community trade; Examine the need to disaggregate a number of livelihood or production activities; Consider extending the multiplier analysis based on marginal propensities for expenditures; Transform the SAM analysis into a dynamic model by conducting a computable general equilibrium analysis. Enhance resource modeling by including other non-timber resources exploited by the community; and 8. Consider some refinements in the simulation by incorporating precise data on fire damage and natural mortality. 155 LITERATURE CITED Abaza, H. (editor). 1992. The present state of environmental and resource accounting and its potential application in developing countries. UN Environmental Economics Series No. 1, United Nations, New York, USA. Acharya, M. 1982. Time use data and the living standards measurement study. Living standards measurement study Working Paper No. LSM [8 World Bank. Alocilja, E. C. 1990. Process Network Theory. In Proceedings of the I 990 IEEE International Conference on Systems, Man, and Cybernetics, 4-7 November 1990, Los Angeles, CA, pp. 66-71. Appendini, K., M. Nuijten, and V. Rawal. I999. Rural household income strategies and interactions with the local institutional environment: a methodological framework. Sustainability Dimensions http://www.fao.org/waicent/faoinfo/sustdev/ROdirect/ROan0021 .htm (downloaded 5-31-2000) Atkinson, G., W. R. Dubourg, K. Hamilton, M. Munasinghe, D. W. Pearce, C. Young. 1997. Measuring Sustainable Development: Macroeconomy and Environment. Edward Elgar Publishing Cheltenham, UK. Ayers, R.U. and AN. Kneese. "Production, Consumption, and Extemalities," American Economic Review, (59:3), June 1969. pp. 282-297. Bann, C. 1998. The economic valuation of tropical forest land use options: a manual for researchers. Economy and Environment Program for Southeast Asia (EEPSEA), Tanglin, Singapore. Barbier, E. B. 1994. Valuing environmental functions: tropical wetlands. Land Economics, 70: 155-173. Barbier, E. B. and R. Lopez. 1998. Debt, poverty and resource management in a rural smallholder economy. Paper prepared for the World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, Venice, 25-27 June 1998. Bartelmus, P. 1993. Environmental statistics and accounting. Chapter II in A. Markandya and C. Costanza ,editors, Environmental Accounting: A Review Of The Current Debate, United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) Environment And Economics Unit (EEU) Environmental Economics Series Paper No. 8. Harvard Institute for lntemational Development, USA. Bartelmus, P., C. Stahmer, and J. van Tongeren. 1993. Integrated environmental and economic accounting: a framework for an sna satellite system. In: Lutz, E. (ed.) 156 Toward Improved Accounting for the Environment. A UNSTAT - World Bank Symposium. World Bank. Washintong DC, pp.45- 65. Bartelmus, P., E. Lutz, and S. Schweinfest. 1992. Integrated environmental and economic accounting: a case study for Papua New Guinea. Environment Working Paper No. 54. The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA. Becker, GS, 1965. A theory of the allocation of time. The Economic Journal, 75(299):493-517. Beckerman, W. 1994. "Sustainable development': is it a useful concept?" Environmental Values. 3: 191-209. Bratkovich, S (undated). Green certification. USDA Forest Service Northeastern Area State & Private Forestry. http://willow.ncfes.umn.edu/Steve/gmcert.htm (downloaded 10-10-2000). BREDCI, I991. Plano Para Sa Pagpauswag Asin Pagmanehar Kan Mga Rekursus Sa K omunidad Kan C F P Sa Presentacion (A development and management plan for community resources in the C FP, Presentacion). A copy of the document submitted to the Department of Environment and Natural Resources, Diliman, Quezon City, Philippines. Bureau of Economic Analysis, 1994. Accounting for mineral resources: Issues and BEA’s initial estimates. Survey of Current Businesses, April 1994. Bureau of Economic Analysis, 1994. Integrated economic and environmental satellite accounts. Survey of Current Business, April 1994. Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2000. Accounting for renewable and environmental resources. Survey of Current Businesses, March 2000. Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2000. Accounting for subsoil mineral resources. Survey of Current Businesses, February 2000. Cervigni, R. 1998 (Unpublished). Subsistence needs, non-farm employment and tenure conflicts: predicting land use change in Mexico using dynamic stock- flow modelling techniques. Draft of paper for presentation to the World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists. Venezia, Italy, June 25-27, 1998 Commission of the European Communities, lntemational Monetary Fund, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, United Nations, and World Bank, 1993. System of National Accounts I 993. Brussels/Luxembourg, New York, Paris, Washington, DC. Costanza, R. and H. E. Daly. 1987. Toward an ecological economics. Ecological Modelling 38: l-7. Costanza, R., I. Cumberland, H. Daly, R. Goodland, and R. Norgaard. 1997. An Introduction To Ecological Economics. St. Lucie Press, Boca Raton, Florida, USA. Darmstadter, J., 2000. Greening the GDP: Is it desirable? Is it feasible? In: Resource Spring 2000 Issue I 39. Resources for the Future pp.l l-15. de Guzman, G. G. 1991. Natural resource accounting and system of national accounts. A technical paper presented at the Natural Resource Accounting Project Final Workshop, National Institute of Geological Sciences, UP Diliman, Quezon City, October 15, I991. 29 p. Defoumy, J. and E. Thorbecke. 1984. "Structural path analysis and multiplier decomposition within a social accounting matrix framework." The Economic Journal 94: l 1 l-l36. Delos Angeles, M. S. 1995. Integrating socio-economic and environmental policies: a cursory review. Paper presented at the IEMSD Workshop, August I, 1995, DENR Quezon City Philippines. Department of Environment and Natural Resources, United Nations Development Program and National Economic Development Authority. 1996. A Case Study on the Compilation of Natural Resource Accounts in the Philippines. Quezon City Philippines. Department of Environment and Natural Resources. 1991. The Philippine Natural Resources Accounting Project (ENRAP-Phase 1) Executive Summary (Photocopied) Ehui, S. K. and D. S.C. Spencer, 1993. Measuring the sustainability and economic viability of tropical farming systems: a model for sub-saharan africa. Ag. Econ 9:279-296. El Serafy, S. and E. Lutz. 1989. Environmental and resource accounting: an overview. Pages l-7 in Y. J. Ahmad, S. El Serafy, and E. Lutz, editors, Environmental Accounting For Sustainable Development. The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA. ENRAP 4 (Author unspecified) Detailed work plan: Environmental and Natural Resources Accounting Project Phase IV. (printed copy of electronically acquired material). Francisco, H. A. 1991. Application of the proposed valuation framework to watershed resources. Natural Resources Accounting Project Final Workshop Tech Rep. 9. National Institute of Geological Sciences, U.P. Diliman, Quezon City, Philippines Oct. 15,1991. 158 Friend, A. M. and D. J. Rapport. I990. The evolution of information systems for sustainable development. Occasional Paper No. I . Institute for Research on Environment and Economy, Ottawa, Canada. Friend, AM. 1993. Feasibility of environmental and resource accounting in developing countries. Chapter IV In: A. Markandya and C. Costanza ,editors, Environmental Accounting: A Review Of The Current Debate, United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) Environment And Economics Unit (EEU) Environmental Economics Series Paper No. 8. Harvard Institute for lntemational Development, USA. Friend, Anthony M. and David J. Rapport. 1991. "evolution of macro-information systems for sustainable development," Ecological Economics 3:59-76. Gale, R. P. and S. M. Cordray, 1991. "What should forests sustain? Eight answers." J. For. May 1991. Grambsch, A. E., R. G. Michaels, and H. M. Peskin. 1993. Taking stock of nature: environmental accounting for Chesapeake Bay. Pages 184-197 in E. Lutz, editor, Toward Improved A ccounting for the Environment. A UN Stat-World Bank Symposium, IBRD-World Bank, New York, USA. Grootaert, C. 1982. The conceptual basis of measurement of household welfare and their implied surveys data requirements. Living Standards Measurement Stuay' Working Paper No. LSM I 9 World Bank. Grosh, M. E. and P. Glewwe, 1995. A guide to living standard measurement surveys and their data sets. LSMS Working Paper No. I 20. The World Bank. Washington DC. Hartwick, J.M., 1990. "Natural resources, national accounting and economic depreciation ", Journal of Public Economics, 43:291-304. Hawrylyshyn, O., 1976. "the value of household services: a survey of empirical results," Review of Income and Wealth, (1976): 101-132. Hecht J. E. and H. M. Peskin, 1993. Natural resource accounting in the developing world: a neoclassical approach: a summary. Summary of a paper by the same title presented at the Committee of International Development Institutions on the Environment (C IDIE) Workshop on Environmental and Natural Resources accounting, United Nations Environment Programme, Nairobi, Kenya, February 24-26, 1992. High Performance Systems, 1996. STELLA 3.0.7 Student Authoring Version. Mac2Win Porting Technology, Altura Software Inc. Hoffren, J. 1997. Finnish forest resource accounting and ecological sustainability. Tutkimuksia F orskningsrapporter Research Report 224, Helsinki, Finland. 159 Hueting, R., P. Bosch, and B. de Boer, 1992: Methodology for the calculation of sustainable national income. Chapter V. In A. Markandya and C. Costanza (eds), Environmental accounting: a review of the current debate, United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) Environment And Economics Unit (EEU) Environmental Economics Series Paper No. 8. Harvard Institute for lntemational Development, USA Hufschmidt, M., D. James, A. Meister., B. Bower and J. Dixon. 1983. Environment, natural Systems, and Development: an Economic Valuation Guide, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press. lntemational Resource Group, Edgevale Associates, and Resources, Environment and Economics Center for Studies, 1996. The Philippine Environmental and Natural Resources Accounting Project. Main Report Phase 11]. Resource, Environment and Economics Center for Studies. Quezon City, Philippines lntemational Union for Forestry Research Organizations (IUFRO), 1997 "Recent developments in accounting and managerial economics for an environmentally- friendly forestry" presented in the final session of the International IUFRO - INRA Symposium by Prof. Maurizio Merlo. Nancy, France, 21-23 April 1997 p 5. lRG/Edgevale/REECS. I996. ENRAP (Environmental and Natural Resources Accounting Project) I 11 main report. Report prepared for the Department of Environment and Natural Resources and the United States Agency for lntemational Development, lntemational Resources Group, Ltd., Washington, DC; Edgevale Associates, Virginia. USA; and Resources, Environment and Economics Center for Studies, Inc., Quezon City, Philippines. James, H. S, Jr., 1996. "The valuation of household production: How different are the opportunity cost and market price valuation methods?" working paper #ewp- mic/9612001, Economic Working Paper Archive,. University of Hartford. JObstl, H., J. Hogg. 1998. On the state of forest accounting in some European countries. In: Recent Developments In Accounting And Managerial Economics For An Environmentally-Friendly Forestry. lntemational IU FRO - [NRA Symposium, Nancy. 21 - 23 April 1997. Keuning, S. and Ruijter, W. -l988 Guidelines to the construction of a social accounting matrix. Review of Income and Wealth, 34(1):7l-101. Kiekens, J. P., 1999. Forest certification, Part II: Impacts on forestry, trade and consumer information. Engineered Wood Journal - Spring 2000 Edition. http://sfcw.org/forest_certification_part2.htm (downloaded 10-10-2000). King, Dennis M.. Curtis C. Bohlcn and Pierre R. Crosson, 1995. "Natural resource accounting and sustainable watershed management: With illustration for the upper mississippi river watershed," A Report for the President's Council on Sustainable Development, UMD Ref. No. UMCEES CBL-95-037, February 1995 160 Leefers, LA. and GB. Castillo. I998. Bridging the gap between economics and ecology. Conservation Ecology [online] 2(2): 19. http://www. consecol.org/J oumal/v012/ issZ/art 1 9/ Lopez-Gonzaga, V. B., 1994. People initiated environmental education, rehabilitation and conservation: a case study of Cauayan, Negros Island, Philippines SEAMEO— Jasper Fellowship Monograph, 1994 Series 2 In:http://www.seameo.org/vl/library/dlwelcome/publications/ebook/jasper/mono9 4.htm downloaded January 05, 2001. Lutz, E. 1993. Toward improved accounting for environment: an overview. Pages 1-14 in E. Lutz, editor, Toward Improved A ccounting for the Environment. A UN Stat- World Bank Symposium, IBRD-World Bank, New York, USA. Lutz, E. and S. El Serafy, 1988. Environmental and resource accounting :an overview. Policy Planning and Research Staff World Bank Environment Department Working Paper No. 6. Washington, DC. Maler, KG. 1992. "Production function approach in developing countries." In: Vincent, J.R., Crawford, E.W. and Hoehn, J.P. (eds.) Valuing Environmental Benefits in Developing Countries. Special Report 29. Michigan State University. Maler, KG. 1991. National accounts and environmental resources. Environmental and Resource Economics, 1 : 1-15. Markandya , A. and C. Perrings. 1993. Accounting for an ecologically sustainable development: a summary. Chapter I in A. Markandya and C. Costanza ,editors, Environmental Accounting: A Review Of The Current Debate, United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) Environment And Economics Unit (EEU) Environmental Economics Series Paper No. 8. Harvard Institute for lntemational Development, USA. Miller, RE. and PD. Blair, 1985. Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions. Prentice-Hall, Inc. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey. Munasinghe, M.and E. Lutz. 1991. Environmental-economic evaluation of projects and policies for sustainable development. The World Bank Sector Policy And Research Staff Environmental Working Paper No. 42. (See also Peskin and Peskin 1978). Nordhaus, W. and J. Tobin. 1972. Is growth obsolete? In: Economic Growth, National Bureau of Economic Research General Series #96E. Columbia University Press, New York, New York, USA. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1995. Environmental Accounting for Decision-making. OECD Working Papers n0. 65. Paris 1995. 161 Perman, R., Y. Ma, and J. McGilvray. Natural Resource & Environmental Economics,lst Ed. London: Addison Wesley Longman Ltd, 1998. Peskin H M. 1998. Alternative resource and environmental accounting approaches and their contribution to policy. In: Environmental Accounting in Theory and Practice, pp. 375-394, edited by K Uno and P Bartelmus Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. 459 pp. Peskin H., W. Floor, and D. Barnes. 1992. Accounting for traditional fuel production: the household energy sector and its implications for the development process. Industry and Energy Department, Operations Division, The World Bank. October 1992. Peskin, H. 1989. Environmental and non-market accounting in developing countries. Pages 59-64 in Y. J. Ahmad, S. El Serafy, and E. Lutz, editors, Environmental Accounting For Sustainable Development. The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA. Peskin, H. 1989. Environmental and non-market accounting in developing countries. In Ahmad, Y. J ., S. E. Serafy, E. Lutz. 1989. Environmental Accounting For Sustainable Development: Selected Papers from Joing UNEP World Bank Workshops. p 59-64. Peskin, H. M. 1993. Sustainable resource accounting. Paper prepared for the International Expert Meeting on Strategies for Sustainable Resource Management and Resource Use, Noordwijk, The Netherlands, June 3-4, 1993. Peskin, H. M. 1996. Alternative resource and environmental accounting approaches and their contribution to policy, paper prepared for the F ondazione Eni Enrico Mattei and presented in Beijing, China and Tokyo, Japan. Published as Nota di Lavoro 77.96 (November). Peskin, H. M., and E. Lutz. 1990. A survey of resource and environmental accounting in industrialized countries. Environment Working Paper Number 3 7. The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA. Peskin, Henry. 1991. "Accounting for Natural Resources Degradation in Developing Countries." In: Vincent, J.R., Crawford, E.W. and Hoehn, J .P. (eds) Valuing Environmental Benefits in Developing Countries. Special Report 29. Michigan State University. Pezzey, John CV. (1992): "Sustainable Development Concepts: An Economic Analysis", World Bank Environment Paper No. 2. Washington, DC: World Bank, November. Prudham, W. S. and S. Lonergan. 1993. Natural resource accounting (1): a review of existing frameworks. Can. J. of Regional Science 16(3):363-386. I62 Prudham, W. S. and S. Lonergan. 1999. Natural Resource Accounting (11): Toward the development of a Regional Model. Can. J. of Regional Science. l6(3):387-412. Prugh, T. 1995. Natural capital and human survival. lntemational Society of Ecological Economics Press, Solomons, New York, USA. Pyatt, G. and J. 1. Round, eds. (1985). Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Pyatt, G. and J.I. Round. 1985. Accounting and fixed-price multipliers in a social accounting matrix framework. Chapter 9 In Pyatt, G. and J. I. Round, eds. (1985). Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Rapport, D. and A. Friend 1979. Towards a comprehensive framework for environmental statistics: a stress response approach. Statistics Canada, Ottawa Repetto, R., W. Magrath, M. Well, C. Beer, and F. Rossini. 1989. Wasting assets: natural resources in the national income accounts. World Resources Institute, Washington, DC, USA. Ruddle, K. and D. A. Rondinelli. 1983. Transforming natural resources for human development: a resource systems framework for development policy. Resource systems theory and methodology Series, no. 1 The United Nations University,http://www.unu.edu/unupress/unubooks/80469e/80469E00.htm#Conte nts (downloaded 3-29-99) Rylander, J. C. 1996. Accounting for nature: a look at attempts to fashion a "green GDP". Renewable Resources Journal 14 (2):8-13. Saama, P. M., M. A. Schipull, and E. Alocilja. I990. Utilization of the process network theory in the analysis of a beef feedlot system. Am. Soc. Agric. Engineers. St. Joseph, MI: The Society. Winter 1990. Paper No. 90-7575. Saxena, R., and R. Agrawal. 1997. Socio-eco-environmental accounting: a proposed framework for tree growers’ co-operatives with a cast study. Institute of Rural Management Anand Working Paper no. 110. Schweitzer, J. 1991. "Economics, conservation, and development: A perspective from USAID." In J. R. Vincent, E. W. Crawford, and J. P. Hoehn, eds., Valuing Environmental Benefits In Developing Countries. Special Report 29, Michigan State University, Agricultural Experiment Station, East Lansing, Michigan. Shaw, W.D. 1992. Searching for the opportunity cost of an individual's time. Land Economics 68: 107-15. 163 Shields, M.D., B. P. Thoman-Slayter, and Clark University, 1993. Gender, class, ecological decline, and livelihood strategies: A case study of Siquijor Island, the Philippines. Ecogen Case Study Series. Clark University, Worcester , MA. Solorzano, R.; de Camino, R.; Woodward, R.; Tosi, J.; Watson, V.; Vasquez, A.; Villalobos, C.; Jimenez, J .; Repetto, R.; Cruz, W. 1991. Accounts overdue: natural resource depreciation in Costa Rica. Tropical Science Centre, San Jose, Costa Rica, and World Resources Institute, Washington, DC, USA. Statistics Canada, 1997. Econnections: Linking the Environment and the Economy; Concepts, Sources and Methods of the Canadian System of Environmental and Resource Accounts. Catalogue no. l6-505-GPE., Ontario. Statistics Canada. 1990. A framework for environmental statistics. (Draft). Environment and Natural Resource Section, Statistics Canada, Ottawa, ON, Canada. Stone, R. 1985. "The disaggregation of the household sector in the national accounts." Chapter 8 In Pyatt, G. and J. 1. Round, eds. (1985). Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Taylor, J. E. and l. Adelman, 1996. Village Economies. New York, Cambridge University Press. Theys, J. 1989. Environmental accounting in development policy. In Y. J. Ahmad, S. El Serafy, and E. Lutz, editors, Environmental accounting for sustainable development. The World Bank, Washington, DC, USA. Theys, J. 1989. Environmental accounting in development policy: the French experience. In Ahmad, Y. J. S. El Serafy, and E. Lutz, eds. 1989. Environmental Accounting for Sustainable Development. UN Environmental Program. World Bank. Washington DC. Pp 40-53 UN Commission on Sustainable Development, 1996. Measuring and capturing forest values: issues policies and challenges. Program Element [1].] (b), Scientific Research. Forest Assessment and Development of Criteria and Indicators for Sustainable Forest Management. Ad Hoc lntergovemmental Panel on Forests Third Session, September 9-20, 1996 United Nations, 1993. Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting. Handbook of National Accounting. United Nations New York, Series F, No. 61 p. 25 . United Nations. 1993. Integrated environmental and economic accounting: interim version. Studies in Methods. Handbook of National Accounting, Series F, No. 61. United Nations Publication, New York, New York, USA. United Nations. 1984 Framework for the development of environment statistics. Statistics Paper, Series M, No. 78 New York: United Nations. 28pp. 164 United Nations. 1991. Concepts and methods of environment statistics: statistics of the natural environment. Studies in methods, Series F, No. 57 New York: United Nations. 159 p. Van Kooten, G. Comelis, 1993. Land Resource Economics and Sustainable Development. Vancouver: UBC Press Vincent, J. F. and J. H. Hartwick. 1997 (unpublished report). "Accounting for the benefits of forest resources: concepts and experience. A report for the FAO Forestry Department. Harvard Institute of International Development," revised draft July 1997 Vincent, J. R. 1998. "Theoretical aspects of forest accounting." Development Discussion Paper No 625 Harvard Institute of lntemational Development 24 p. Watershed-Based Needs Accounting. http://www.epa.gov/owm/wtr.htm William D. Nordhaus and Edward C. Kokkelenberg, (eds). 1999. Nature's numbers: Expanding the national economic accounts to include the environment. Executive Summary. Panel on Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting, Committee on National Statistics Commission on Behavioral and Social Sciences and Education National Research Council. National Academy Press, Washington, DC. 1999 Xu, Zhi, Bradley D.P., Jakes, P.J., 1995. Measuring forest ecosystem sustainability: a resource accounting approach. Environmental Management 19(5): 685-692. Young, M. 1993. Natural resource accounting: some Australian experience and observations. Pages 177-183 in E. Lutz, editor, Toward Improved Accounting for the Environment. A UN Stat- World Bank Symposium, IBRD-World Bank, New York, USA. G LOSSARY Accumulation Accounts - this are flow accounts that record the acquisition and disposal of financial and non-financial assets and liabilities by institutional units through transactions and as a result of other events. Include capital accounts, financial accounts and changes in volume of assets accounts and revaluation accounts (UN, 1993). Balance Sheets - show the value of stocks of assets and liabilities held by institutional units or sectors at the beginning and end of the accounting period (un, 1993) Current Accounts - this account record the production of goods and services, the generation of incomes by production, the subsequent distribution and redistribution of incomes among institutional units, and the use of incomes for purposes of consumption or saving (UN, 1993). Current cost accounting - best approximation of opportunity cost accounting. Assets and goods used in production are valued in their actual or estimated current market prices at the time the production takes place. Also described as replacement cost accounting (UN, 1993). Distribution and Use of Income Accounts - (see SNA, 1993) - consist of articulated set of accounts showing how incomes are: Generated by production; Distributed to institutional units with claims on the value added created by production Redistributed among institutional units, mainly by government units through social security contributions and benefits and taxes; Eventually used by households, government units or non-profit institutions serving households (N PISHs) for purposes of final consumption and saving. Economy - is a general equilibrium system in which interdependent economic activities involving countless transactions between different institutional units are carried out simultaneously. Feedbacks are continually taking place from one type of economic activity to another. (SNA, 1993). Full cost accounting - is life-cycle costing. Life-cycle costing is a method in which both private and social costs are identified with the product, process or activity throughout its commercial life, from raw material acquisition to disposal (Adopted from: Martin Spitze, Robert Pojasek, Francis Robertaccio, Judith Nelson. Accounting and Capital Budgeting for Pollution Prevention, 1993.) Ref: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 1994. Accounting for Sustainable Forestry Management: A Case Study. United Nations Publication. UN Geneva pp 7. 166 Gross domestic product (GDP) is the value of final goods and services produced in the economy (Note: defensive expenditures for environmental degradation or pollution are not reflected in the GDP). Gross value added - the value of output less the value of intermediate consumption and is a measure of the contribution to GDP made by an individual producer, industry or sector. GVA is carried forward into the Distribution of Income Accounts. Historic cost accounting - requires goods or assets used in production to be valued by the expenditures actually incurred to acquire those goods or assets, however far back in the past those expenditures took place. Imputed value or cost - when goods or services are retained for own use, no transactions with other units takes place. In order to record the goods or services in the accounts, internal transactions have to be imputed whereby producers allocate the goods or services for their own consumption or capital formation and valued have to be estimated for them. The purpose of imputation is to capture in the accounts major flows of goods and services actually taking place in the economy that would otherwise be omitted. Opportunity cost, that is, the cost of using, or using up, some existing asset or good in the particular process of production is measured by the amount of benefits that could have been secured by using the asset or good in alternative ways. It is calculated with reference to the opportunities foregone at the time that asset or resource is used, as distinct from the costs incurred as tome time in the past to acquire the asset. Production Accounts - this account records the activity of producing goods and services as defined within the system. Its balancing items is gross value added. System of National Accounts - consist of a coherent, consistent and integrated set of macroeconomic accounts, balance sheets and tables based on a set of internationally agreed concepts, definitions, classifications and accounting rules. It provides an accounting framework within which economic data can be compiled and presented in a format that is designed for purposes of economic analysis. decision-making and policy-making. The SNA records flows and stocks (SNA, I993) 167 APPENDIX A Appendix to Chapter 3 168 Appendix A: Appendix to Chapter 3 A. I. The Household Market Expenditures (Purchase) Function This section elaborates on the market expenditures equation (Equation 2) described in the first section of Chapter 3 where: 2PM.MC. = EPA,(A,) + ZPF,(F,) +21, - (wL + PKK + c) Total agriculture (A) and forest (F) production can be represented as follows: A=AC+AS+AK F=Fc+ Fs+ FK Therefore, A,=A- Ac-AK F5: F- Fc-FK Hence, market expenditures equation above can be expanded as follows: ZPMiMcr = 2PA1(Ai‘Ac‘AK) + ZPFi(Fi'Fc'FK) +21: ‘ IW(LA+LF+LI) + PKK + C] Where: PM, = price of market good i consumed by household Me. = market good i purchased PA. = price of agricultural product i produced PF, = price of forest product i extracted/produced/harvested PK = price of capital goods purchased for production activities 169 Agriculture or forest production and consumption consist of various commodities so that Ac, Fc, AK, and F K actually composed of several commodities i. In which case, A, and Fc = ACl and Fe, = Agricultural good i and Forest good i consumed, respectively AK and FK = AK, and FK, = Agricultural good i and Forest good i used as capital, respectively A and F = A. and F, = total output of agricultural commodity i and forest good i extracted/produced/harvested, respectively. Likewise, labor and capital consist of various categories so that: L = L A, LF_ L1 = LH~ hired labor used for agriculture, forest and other livelihood activities K = AK, PK, and MK = capital goods produced/purchased used in production from agriculture, forest, or market purchased, respectively w = wage rate for labor I = other livelihood or sources of income i = represents specific commodity c = other costs of production activities, or purchased inputs of production, and may include savings needs This expansion of Equation (2) in chapter 3 provides the basis of valuation of various uses of outputs in of production. 170 A.2. Measurement of Natural Resources, and Non-Marketed Consumption This section discusses simple procedures to measure production outputs and their various destinations. Measurement of Natural Resources Directly Consumed by Households Equation (6) in Chapter 3 presented output of each production activity. The proportion of natural resource consumption compared with rate of resources extraction partly addresses the rate of depreciation of resources. To assist in this, a three-step procedure segregates production activities. market and non-market transacted outputs, and isolates natural resources used. 1. Ratio of Production Activitv to Togl Production. The ratio of monetary values of each production activity to total production value reveals the intensity (y) of each production activity: i P... (n. > .Yn==‘__——_—’— RH h where: i= 1,...a, commodity n = agriculture (A), forestry (F) , or other livelihood activities (I) h = hth household SothatyA+yF+yl=l 171 These ratios are useful coefficients for determining intensity of agricultural, forestry or other livelihood activities. Any changes introduced by external factors potentially shifts intensity of production activity. 2. Production outputs retained by household for consumption and invested in own-production or other production activities compose the non-marketed component of production. These values (using market price) divided by the value of total production estimates the ratio of non-marketed outputs to production: (2 Z Pm. (nu. + n + n, ) i=1 r,, - ratio of non-market-transacted production RH h output to total household production. where: i= 1,...a, commodity n = agriculture (A), forestry (F) , or other livelihood activities (I) h = hth household RH, = total value of production of household h However, ra+ r, + r,< l, where r represents ratio of non-marketed production output to total production, and the subscript a. f and I represent agriculture forestry and other livelihood outputs, respectively. Thus, 1- (r,,+ r/ + r,) represents the ratio of marketed component of production. 172 3. Ratios of natural resources sold and directly consumed completes the accounting of natural resource exploitation. The ratio of natural resources consumed or used for other production activities (calculated using this three-step process) to total consumption and intensity of production activity partially explains the state of natural resources and its sustainability over time. A.3. Mathematical Model of Household Decision to Shifl Production Activities Predicting the pattern of production activity shifts between three production options - agriculture, forestry, and non-land based production — provide altematjve approaches to estimation of natural resource use over time. The income-expenditure identity equation, that represents the decision function for the household to shift production, provides the framework in this approach. Under a condition of inequality of the expenditure-receipts function (Equation 3 of Chapter 3): sziMcr + (WL + PKK + C) = ZPAkAs) + ZPFI(F5) +21. From the Receipt side: The value of marginal product (MVP) of inputs of production alternatives provides logical basis for making production choices. VMP is simply translated as the value of a marginal unit of the output by employing a particular input. The 173 value of marginal product (MVP) from Agriculture, Forestry or other production activities: VMPn : Pm(."r) where n refers to agricultural (A), forestry (F) or other production activities (I). The right-hand-side refers to per unit value of output by employing a particular input in a production activity. Three different conditions mays arise so that household decisions under three different conditions are: 0 VMPA and VMP, < VMPF, household will shift resources to forest exploitation o VMPA and VMP}: < VMPI, household will shift resources to other livelihood activities 0 VMPI and VMPI. < VMPA, household will shift resources to agricultural production. The three conditions show that differences in marginal value product determine the choice and intensity of a production activity. However, the household conducts production activities so that the identity equation holds, thus, they may have primary and secondary production activities to meet minimum basic needs. Hence, a minimum combination of production activity exists, i.e. agriculture and forest, forest and other livelihood or agriculture and other hvehhood. Under perfect market conditions VMP = P.. Therefore, if PA < PF, households will shift to forest production. 174 From the Expenditure side: Households decision options may be: Substitute for hired labor with family labor, Substitute for purchased market goods with own production (i.e., pharmacological products with medicinal plants), Substitute for purchased capital goods with substitute capital from production activities (i.e., housing materials such as metal roofs with indigenous materials harvested from forest), and Substitute for other purchased cost by exploiting "free goods" (i.e., use river water for laundry instead of purchasing piped water). 175 APPENDIX B Appendix to Chapter 4 I76 APPENDIX B. APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 4 B. I Survey Questionnaire ( Translated from Tagalog) NATURAL RESOURCE ACCOUNTING FRAMEWORK FOR THE COMMUNITY-BASED FOREST RESOURCE MANAGEMENT (CBF M) SYSTEM OF THE PHILIPPINES S UR VE Y QUESTIONNAIRE Dear . I am Gem Castillo, a student of Michigan State University in the United States. You were chosen by the researcher to answer thisquestionaire. I am presently conducting a study on natural resource accounting. Your community had been choosen as one of the places of study. This interview is estimated to last for more or less one to two hours. If needed, we will add another 30 minute at other times if more answers are needed. Questions are related to your livelihood activities in the farm, forest within or adjacent to your community. You may not participate in the interview if in your opinion, will cause harm to you by giving out information. Your answers will not be reported. Only the group of researchers will the contents of the interview. Your name will not be written in the questionnaire. The completed questionnaire will be handed and handled by Gem Castillo. You may ask for the summary report of interviews if you request. If you have some questions or doubts on the interview please, send us a letter through this addresseszz Mr. Gem B. Castillo, Dr. Larry Leefers, l4-A Bellamaja Townhomes Department of Forestry, 411 Aglipay St., Mandaluyong, 126 Natural Resources Building, Metro Manila, 1550 Michigan State University, Telephone no. (63-2) 532-1557 East Lansing, MI 48824, Tel 517-355-0097 177 Respondent no. Time Started: Barangay: Time Finished: Sitio/Purok: Interviewer: Place: (House 0 a place) Date: Read the introductory letter and if the respondent agrees to the interview check this box [I Questionnaire (Translated) For the interviewer: Please answer the following questions honestly: iMINIMUM BASIC NEEDS A What are the basic needs of your household? (A “household ” used in this interview include only actual residents and excludes members of the family living in another household. Included in the "household ” are members of the family not physically living in the house but are dependent on the income generated by the household such as children in school outside of the community). 1. What kind of food do you need on a daily basisz? (Please make sure to indicate the quantity) Food1 How much What is How Where do o. is needed in your unit of much you get/buy '3 E 0 one day/ measure?3 does one these? (Use E *5 ‘8 week/ unit the codes ’5 E 0 month?2 cost? below)4 2 E Code I Rice. vegetables, meat. salt, sugar, coffee. milk, spices, water, etc. 2 It is likely that respondents will provide answers to certain items used not on a daily basis, in which case indicate in the “Other information column " the frequency metioned. 3 Units of measure: kilograms. bdft. meters, (Refer to conversion table) 4 SA =from own agricultural land (A &D land): SG =homemade: C SC =from C erti. 0f Stewardship C ontrac land (forest land); G=from natural forest; B=bought from market or grocery; BL=bought from within village; D=donation; BR=barter. 178 2. What are your daily clothingneeds? Clothin What do How much do What is the How Where do Needs" you use? you use in one unit of much is you get day/week/mont measure?2 the cost or buy? 8 h/year? of one Use 8 unit? codes below3‘ Code TLaundry soap, materials used for ironing e. g. charcoal or electric, materials used for laundry and how much is used per day, etc. 2 Units of measure: kilograms, bdft, meters, (Refer to conversion table for calculations) 3 SA =from own agricultural land (A &D land) ,' SG =homemade; CSC=fiom C erti. 0f Stewardship C ontrac land «orest land); G=from natural forest; B=boughtfiom market or grocery: BL =bought from within village; D=donation,' BR=barter (Two or more answers is likely) 4 Note: The purchase of clothing is not considered a daily requirement. although many allot for needs such as school uniforms. With this in mind, ask how many school uniform are bouth each year. If otherwise , (no school uniform) ignore the item and indicate only expenses for clothing. 179 3. What are your daily health needs? [:I Whatare g. _5 O.) . yourhealth 3 x- O r: o 30 “m 3, ...= 1: O 'c o“, .x needs? 0% g 3 >,; E _go- >23 3 a a) S I “:30 >~° go.) 0': oo-o E 'O eeexampes .. m m E o a) :3 o 1: EB a, o belowL3 .2 3 :E E m Q3)“ E °‘ 3 ”'D : U NH ;=\S am 050.) U 3 .::-- :>. :3 4:...1: .: : com” 0o oo ... 3:: Ix-cb I» 3600 0 Code 1 Examples: headache medicine: medicine for other ailment; bath soap; shampoo: toothpaste. atbp. 2 Exmples: tablet, tube (toothpaste), bar soap. Do not use brand name here 3 Note: Include free medicine from Health Center and indicate in appropriate boxes. For addition answers not appropriate for the boxes include ”Other remarks" (Last column). 4 SA =from own agricultural land (A&D land) ,' SG =homemade; CSC=from Certi. 0f Stewardship C ontrac land forest land) ; G =from natural forest; B=bought from market or grocery; BL =bought from within village: D=d0nation; BR=barter 4. Do you have education expenses? Yes D No D Level of education? What types and how much Tuition Transportion Meals Others? Pre-School: Elementary: High School: College: 180 5. What argyour household assets/properties? Household c~- H . Q) 000 . assets/propertiesI .51.! :3)- g 5 are“? S), o 51: -= a- :52 9‘ >» m 0 o o {a ... 8 A *- 8. >01: 0 ‘7’ 3%; 3- : 030 E P E :3. a— 0 13:13 ‘— o :3 500v 0 g) 028 B U 0 g8 ‘95 a; gel» 5 ..D (It 0 2 3‘5: 0 Code I A ppliances, dressers, kitchenwares, dining wares, sala set, tables etc. NOTE: This should not include farm implements and machinery used in livelihood/production activities) 2 SA =from own agricultural land (A &D land) : SG =homemade; C SC =from C erti. Of Stewardship C ontrac land (forest land); G=jrom natural forest; B=bought from market or grocery; BL=boughtfiom within village: D=donation; BR =barter (Two or more answers is likely) 181 6. Description of the house Floor area of the house? How old is the house? (year) Types of materials used in the house? (Write answer inside cell or box) House m 0 a E " a e- '-.: =9; "- component 5;; 3 s. a, q, q, a ... e a a, - E 'c-rfi cm-g *- um =0 0 G am «53°». augme- EU 60 o «2: 335°: Efg§° 32 2:36 9“ .= no '5 gr: 0.. 4:“ has ‘0ng, “GE = ¢u > “a t-EB.2=.:>.:: m£a3=:.2 <8'OS Code I Measurement and quantity of house panelings/walls, roofing, flooring, and if these was made of wood, concrete. or native materials etc. 2 SA =from own agricultural land (A&D land); so =homemade; CSC =from Certi. 0f Stewardship C ontrac land (forest land) ; G =from natural forest; B=bought from market or grocery; BL=bought from within village; D=donation; BR=barter (Two or more answers is likely) 182 7. If your daily needs can be bought, what is the total amount you would have to spend? (How much is needed to supply your daily needs? This is considered the budget of the household) a. P50-99 E] b. moo-149 E] c. P 150-199 E] d. 9200-249 [3 e. P250-299 E] f. P300-349 [I g. P350-399 [:1 h. P400-over E] 8. What do you substitute for those needs you are unable to buy or those bought in the market, store, grocery, drug store or hardware? Explain: It is possible this is due to lack financial resources or other reasons. (Note: The respondent may not be needy or lack financial resource but substitutes items anyway. Explain clearly so that their intention for substitution is understood) Regularly What is What are your sources for substittues?3 purchased your 2 . l . :3 C‘- q) rtems substitute? :9 3 5 o o 2 ° 3 5 E {-5 § 2‘?» <3 8 E {I}: 3 e 3 9: (U I: o. S b' O .2: m 3 “g a 3 “g E 3 “EH: >~ a ‘5 = *5 O O *5 O O O O a O {-3 O D a... :1: o c... I 0 ct— I o 0.0 Q o m Code I Vegetables. meat, salt. sugar, coflee, milk, water, etc?, For health?, For clothing? (You may refer to previous question) I These could be of dlflerent type such as sweet potatio as substitute for rice. 3 Example: All = I 00%; Half = 50%; quarter = 25 %; Otherwise record the quantity. 183 9. Where do you get your fuel or energy source? Type of F uell Where was How many What is it getd or do you need your unit of purchased? per day?3 measure? Use codes below2 How much is one unit? Do you have other commen I Example: Gas (LPG), Kerosene. charcoal (separate those produced from wood and coconut shell), wood, electric... etc 2 Of Stewardship C ontrac land (forest land) ,' G =from natural forest; B=boughtfiom market or grocery; BL =bought from within village; D=donation; BR=barter (Two or more answers is likely)SA =from own agricultural land (A &D land) ; SG=homemade; CSC=from C erti. 3 It is likely that the respondent do not measure daily use. Record the quantity in this column. Record other comments in the 10. What is the price of fuel within the last column. community? Type of fuel What is the unit of measure? What is the price per unit? What conversion factor do you use? sol-sew:- 184 B. SOURCE OF INCOME OR LIVELIHOOD What are your sources of income or livelihood? Check the appropriate box. 11. Do you have a farm? Yes 1:] None [I Livelihood in the farm What is How oftenly do you work? (Check you the appropriate category) total 2 . 0 income? D g Z _< 9. 5,3" I a t s 3 :2 ;. a. ‘ (D Code 9’99 e f. g. h DDDDDDDD DDDDDDDD DDDDDDDD DDDDDDDD DDDCIEIEIEICI I Example: Planting vegetables; Planting, care, and harvesting coconut; Planting and harvesting rice; Planting and harvesting corn; C opra production; Planting and harvesting fruit trees 2 Example: 2t = twice a year. 3t = three times a year, etc. ; 2w = twice a week. etc; 2b = twice per month. etc; 185 12. If you have a farm, please answer the followin c uestions? Type of farm 2’, 3 c: 33 .. a >- \ . . 5 .§ g g a; a a E a = ”a. '- o O 1: 0 o- ? $33 a E ““3 €52 g o _‘ cm 0 E ‘3 E5 33 g 3 § ‘5' e g 3 'g o g “r 8 $3. >‘ 5 3" 8 a? '99 § '5 g a? 2 g g o a a a .E 3 L8 a: c: 3 a: o z r Rice paday, cornfield. peanut farm, C SC . fruit orchard et. 2 Specijj) the river or stream where the irrigation water flows. 13. What are your farm ex enses? What are c~- :: ,...; N your cost g g g o. .fg’ "$2 5 "3:” 5 items?1 E ‘3 .22 k 2 a 8 o. 3'5 3}, E 3.8 2:§ Séae gés 8 :1: 8. a 3 5 E 3 «2: «t u l— m u 0 Example: 3 bags 3 P420 3 780 50kg/ bag Fertilizer Labor 14 Daily 2 125 3500 8/hrs/d ‘ Example: F ertilizer. insecticide, herbicide, gas, labor, food. kahoy, vine. water, etc. 2 Explain the conversion to kilogram. meters. cubic meters, liters 3 Need not compute the total. 186 14. What tools and equipment do you use in farming? Farming Where do How How ofien How much Other implement or you get or many? do you per unit? comments?3 tooll buy? Use replace? code below2 TExmple: Water buffalo, cart, thresher, plow, dryer etc. 2 0f Stewardship C ontrac land (forest land); G =from natural forest; B=boughtfiom market or grocery; BL =bought from within village; D=donation; BR=barter (Two or more answers is likely) SA =fiom own agricultural land (A &D land); SG =homemade; CSC =from C ertificate of Stewardship contract lands Example: Price not known 15 . What are your output from the farm? Type of Output 1, 3'5 5 a s '6 B 2 13 2 w J: o “U :— m m C m C‘ -- 8 Q— E d) a) H 3 .fl 3 '6 _g 2‘ Q5 3 0) 8 G g G g_ (:0, T) .... ,_ a.) s... ..C: s— o - g t: g‘ a. a) o o :3 D G- O- l— G) O’ f-L r State average or normal production output insteaqd of current output that were aflected by typhoon or other natural calamity. 2 Note: If you use quantity in one cell do the same fiom in all the rest. 187 16. Do you have livelihood activities in the forest? Yes None Occasionally D Forest Livelihood Activityl How a N much 3; a r a a *5 8 (10 cc 8 § 2 0 g. 0 you Q 3 >.. .5 3: 3:, L) earn? 2 Code DIDICJIEJIDDIDI Mommy Dmpmmpu almlmhjlalmlw DIDIDIDID'DID DIDIDlEIIEJIDID I Wood harvesting for charcoal production; Harvesting and marketing lumber; White clay mining; Trapping wildlife; Wood cutting for firewood; Collecting vines; Other Livelihood . Mentiond if this is C SC or Natural forest 2 Example: 2/t = twice a year, 3/t = 3 times a year, etc. ; 2/w = twice a week. etc. ; 2/b = twice per month. etc. ,' ht = not definite/regular 17. What are expenses in forest activities? What are «‘3‘ U N: your 3.; 5 CE) g C C‘- a... C‘- “a expensle g ‘g g: .3 h .5 E -; g g a) g E 0 items? '8 E 2 I; 3 3 0 a) 5 .t: 3 5 = 553 35%; :EES 82-; [3% 8 E Example: 3 Bags 3 P420 3780 5 0kg/ Fertilizer bag Labor 14 Daily 2 125 3500 8-hrs/d I Sample answer: Fertilizer (sa CSC holders), insecticide, herbicide, gasoline, labor, food, wood, vines, water, etc. 2 Explain how the units are converted to standard unit of measures such as kilogram. meters, cubic meters, liters etc. 188 18. What forestry tools and implements do you own? Forestry tools Where do you How Frequency if Cost per Other and implement1 get or buy? many? replacement? unit? comment Use codes 5? belowz 7 Example: Water bufallo cart, thresher, plow. coconut dryer. 2 SA =from own agricultural land (A &D land); SG=homemade; CSC=frorn C erti. 0f Stewardship Contract land (forest land) ,' G=fiom natural forest; B=boughtfrom market or grocery; BL=bought from within village; D=donation; BR =barter (T wo or more answers is likely) 19. What do you harvest from the forest? (With or without permanent livelihood in the forest) Products harvestedI Unit of measure used Percent used for Price per unit Percent sold household Percent use for farming? Percent used for other livelihood Quantity harvested rExample: timber, vines, wildlife, white clay, bamboo, rattan, herbs or medicinal plants etc. 189 20. What forest products do you use for other livelihood? Products Use Quantity or percent used from the Used for Forestry Sold in the Other Used in forest? farming? market livelihood household Example: 100% Na Na Na Na Wood Medicinal Na Na 50% Na 50% plants 21. Do you an experience in harvesting timber from the forest? Yes 1:] No 1:] 22. What species of timber have you harvested? Timber species Volume in cu m? Destination? Price per cu m? 23. What is the frequency of timber harvesting in a year? 190 24. Based on your experience, and having the right condition, how much timber can you harvest? Materials How much can one person accomplish in one da 1 Quantity harvested Unnof measure? of Number hours Q— 02m 330333 efiez's m oil-0 :80> 8 Z.:E.E U harvesting Other comments2 I (Factors aflecting this include demand, quantity of available resources, activities within the community such as house construction, and need or requirement. More importantly, this all depends on the capacity of one person.) 2 Include expense items. 25. How far is the forest from your house? (Note: This refers to the boundary of the forest) Hours walked? (= 0 if household resides within the forest) Distance in kilometers? (= 0 if household resides within the forest) 26. What are your other activities other than your regular livelihood activities in the forest? What are your activities?l Frequency of visits? Duration? How much do you spend? Other comments? 1 Include hobbies such as wildlife trapping, willplants collection, going with others on timber harvesting activities etc. 191 27. What are substitutes for natural resources that you harvest? (Are there substitutes when natural resources are exhausted?) Forest Resources’ Substitute Where do you get or buy the substitute? Use code below2 1 Example: Metal sheets substitute for anahao leaves used for roofing; medicine tablets substitute for medicinal plants, bricks substitute for timber,.. etc. 2 SA =fiom own agricultural land (A &D land); SG =homemade; CSC=from C erti. Of Stewardship C ontrac land aorest land); G=fi0m natural forest; B=b0ught from market or grocery; BL=bought from within village; D=donation; BR=barter (Two or more answers is likely) 28. In your opinion. how much fores resources remains at present? (Optional - Ask the respondent if he/she has knowledge of this.) Forest resources What is the unit of measure? Quantity? What conversion factor do you use? 192 29. Do you have other livelihood activities besides farming and forestry? Yes [:1 No C] Other LivelihoodI income? Yearly Not definite/ regular How How much is your Daily frequent2 DIDFDIDID 1:1 1:1 1311311211121 [II Weekly D'DID'D'EI'D Monthly :1 EJCIIEJD [:1 01:11am“: 13' TCoconut lumber production; carpentry; blacksmith; dress making; retail store (groceries); basket-making, home décor; tiger grass broom-making; jeepney driver; other forest activities: coconut production helper. Wage employment is not included here. but covered by the next question. 2 Example: 2/t = twice a year, 3/t = 3 times a year, etc. ; 2/w = twice a week. etc: 2/b = twice a month. etc; ht = no definite/regular 30. What are your expenditures for these activities? What are CM :1 N your g cg: {‘5’ ~— 2 E 5 § __ 6;"; .5 o expenditure E 33 "3 ”13,: g E 2‘ g 8 g g '8 items?‘ 3 “3 g g o 3 3 a) [3 a g u :3 9 a E :E E 9 «’5 ° 9- ': a. 0 Example: 3 s bags 3 P420 3 780 5 0kg/ Fertilizer bag Labor 14 Daily 2 125 3500 8-hrs/d r Sample answer: Fertilizer. insecticide, herbicide, gasoline. labor, food, wood, vine, water. etc. 2 Explain how the units are convereted to standard unit of measures such as kilogram. meters, cubic meters. liters etc. 193 31. What tools/equipment do you use for these livelihood activities? What tools/ Where do you How How What is Other equipment?l get or buy? Use many? frequent do the price comments? code below2 you replace? per unit? I Example: Water buflalo, cart, thresher, plow, coconut dryer. 2 SA =from own agricultural land (A&D land) ; SG =homemade; CSC=fiom Certi. Of Stewardship C ontrac [and (forest land); G =from natural forest; B=bought from market or grocery; BL=bought from within village; D=donation; BR=barter (Two or more answers is likely) 32. What are your products (off-farm production)? Name of product1 Quantity produced Unit of measure Price per unit Percent sold Percent for 'o 5 —- c... O ... -= t: 3}, o a .4: O... farm? Percent used for other livelihood I Example: wood. vines, wildlife, white clay, bamboo. rattan. etc. 194 33. Is there a member of the household who works for wages or employee in the community or outside the community in the current year? Yes [:1 None I] Occassionally [:1 34. What kind of work? Kind of workI How much is the salary? Choose appropriate answer) 2: I? g 39 SD 3": 3 82-3 5 8 E 5 2 E g “3’. Q 3 2 >‘ *5 % e Z ‘14—: a. Example: Carpenter (2”I 125 na na na na 5/w, ht child) b. c. d. e. f. g. h. i. 1 Example: Write the type of work of the respondent and other members: carpenter, farm labor. wage labor. community oficer ..etc. 2 Example: 2/t = twice a year. 3/t = 3 times a year, etc. ; 2/w = twice a week. etc; 2/b = twice a month. etc; ht = not definite/regular 195 35. Record on a montly basis all activities mentioned above (All: farm, forest and off-farm). (What are your monthly activities each month?) Livelihood . .d a h; E? c.‘ _ oh a. .5 >' 0 .§ a :2 .3 2 £3 -2 2 a; £5 :5 5 Example: _ _ _ Planting _ _ _ Harvest How much is your income per month? (Indicate the livelihood activity) TOTAL How much do ou s end each month? (Write expense items and value) Example: 35 35 35 Fertilizer 00 00 00 TOTAL 196 36. Where do you spend your livelihood income? Livelihoodl Calculate the proportion or percent for each column SNA 5 76' = “O = a.) g -c a? 3 if) 3 E, 8 “:3” 3 3i) 3 E '5 0 -= <6 = 3 a 5 = a .E v o Q 0 ‘5 8 .2 o o T, 8. 2 > 5 8 9, u. a “U m 5 III .2 x 8 (2 O The enumerator/interviewer should list all livelihood activities. 2 Indicate total income from production. K. OTHER SOURCES OF MONEY INCOME 37. Do you have other sources if your livelihood income is not enough? What is your How How often do Respondent's lnterviewer's source?l much? you receive it? explanation Comments I Example: Money remitted by other members of the family working in other places; house/land rent, inheritance. donation. etc 197 D. Leisure and Recreation 38. What are your recreation activities? Recreation activity” How frequent and how many hours? Not definite How equent? How many hours? DDDDDDfi "3.09-9.69 I DDDDDD WW DDDDDDWWY DDDDDDMWW DDDDDDYWy DDDDDD Card games, watching TV, basketball, social drinking, story-telling, wildlife hunting, cockfighting..etc. Sample question for interviewer: "A fter farming, forestry, fishing, what are your other activities other than sleeping? " 2 Ask if this is LA = outside the community; G = inside the forestt; [L = river; 0 = other places (may speczfiz exact place) E. HEALTH AND ENVIRONMENTAL SANITATION 39. Did anybody in your household got ill this past 3 years? What is it? What was the cause? Who got ill? Do not Type of illness? What was the suspected cause? mention name.I ’ Write only the relationship with the respondent, not the name. 198 40. Do you have a toilet? (Check appropriate column) Yes I] No Inside or Water Sealed Open Privy DroppedI OverhangI outside the and Sanitary Pitl house? Pitl I The Interview should describe what each choices mean. 41. Where do you dispose your waste? Check propriate column. Typeof 9' 13 waste. 0 _O = 1,33 8 3 o ..t: m i- "m 3.5 3 8. B? 9373'? a"? Egg 5. E ‘52 33% = Dent) on U m: Lang 5 Bwastes from the kitchen, plastic, metals, etc.. 42. Did you have opportunities to plant trees ? Yes [I o No C] 43. Where did you plant those trees? Encircle apprpriate answer Own-farm Within the CSC Inside the "protection forest" Surrounding household Other places 99.09:.» 44. What kind of trees did you plant? 45. How many did you plant? 46. Do you have other comments? 199 “uoBoanGH “6 325.3 m 0&6 Q “no 952 aims W Go 9:32 «50.50 9..—om FEEZ—dPFafi A4ZOHF4ODB {Fm FWNmOHTH mm a mm m mm m mm L SEEHlO 308W OBWIXS'M HEXUOM BU H331 woo“ szumnmzmmnm mm? 73 EFEW szsnmoaawZAVv/u BECK 8wPHZEEOO mmh. mom Eogmsém OZHFZDOOOA.‘ mom—dog AéDP90 T V T V T V T 1.84 4,52 0.74 3.22 0.37 623 21582 2.58 0.37 3.04 4467 15.32 4.38 1.37 16.62 4.5 0.74 3,22 074 9.27 300.7 1 70 T V 441 8. 037 0. 4 8. 1. Total V 80.72 128 19.3 8.42 1.37 0.27 4. 15. ‘ID = Dipterocarps or species of the family Dipterocarpaceae; N = non-dipterocarps species T= number of trees per hectare = volume, in cubic meters per hectare 204 H awestable APPENDIX C Appendix to Chapter 5 205 APPENDIX C: Appendices to Chapter 5 C .1 Schematic Model of the SAM. Table 22 shows the schematic model of endogenous and exogenous accounts of the SAM in equation form. The symbols, and numeric symbols sparingly used in subsequent discussions on multipliers, are shown and defined in the table. Table 23 show average propensities for expenditures, A5 and GE (average propensity for leakage) derived from the SAM. These figures measure the contribution or proportion of each account element to total expenditures. If it is assumed that accounts are not related or connected, any exogenous injections into the system will change SAM accounts by a fixed proportion (Ag). In reality, accounts are interconnected so that the resulting change (multiplied by a factor M5) is greater than the value of the injection (multiplied by AE), because there are direct and indirect impacts created by account interconnections. The actual change created is calclated by transforming the average propensities (A5) to a Leontief-type multiplier (ME) through a process that involved matrix inversion. The result, shown in Tables 24, is a matrix of endogenous multipliers (ME) for each endogenous account. These multipliers transmit impacts of exogenous changes around the SAM. 206 3888 258898 8888833888: .89 mo 88> 888 u m n m 88898 88 88888 mo 38m 3:: .8 882, u mo 3:3 5:28 mm H 3888 888:8 mo 3:3. 26: n x2 3:.o8 3.8888 2:. 888.8 88898 (:0 88:: n mx 3888 88808 8838: 88888:: go 8.8:: n P 8:88 :8 8:38:88 .838 :88.» n a: :8. 8 82888: 8:88 no 88:: u “.5 85888:: 838898 88888 8:88 .8 88:: n m< 388 2:: 888.8: 88808 .8 38m 3:: mo :o:8> n mx 3388: 88888 88 Bo: .8 :o:8> n m? 8855 m H N— F +mX H mm % 88:8:8xm 30,—. .38.! 33380:»: a x o 3 P + mi N v:Z H a: 5 n mx 253 23o :8: m 3:88.880 m 8 898 m. a m 80338:. M. o m m I m m m H m 8 X4. > I D X «a < > 888898 398”— m m 82>8< 88:85 8.33m 2:03 8085080 8:80 808:85 8888.: 88>8< 3989: _mSH 22.80 8:0 :8”— mo £98m 8880::— , 35.83: 832$ use—:owoum .....Suah 258 28”.— ”Pigtaoaum «37% 8: go 3:388 88888 88 88888 :8 88:38 8888 .mm 2:3. 207 8:38:88 8.. 8.38088 8.88 88888 8 883. .mm 0.8... 0000.. 0000.. 0000,. 0000.. 0000.. 0000.. 0000.. 0000.. 83:808.”. .30... mm 8.93880: cm .N.0.0 N3. .0 8m00 .920 200.0 .8000 530.0 283 22° :8: mm 8035080 .8 380.0 ¢w0N0 .580 32:0 .880 583: :o8.3338< .880 .2382 88:00:80 .8qu .8382 858888388. ('3 N N N 00.8808 8: 3050 838.890 90.80:. 838 280803 3«0.88.. 8.8088 86:08.. 838 0.8083. 0.2...mEm 8.8088 :8.8..§:m IS"— 8151 w _ l l‘ g l \O _n m .— 09:00 N800 8000 50000 $500 9500 m0000 0:00 8000 0N000 083.0 mm000 3.00.0 8.00 0.N0.0 8.0.0 £88 0 0000.0 880.0 mm~00 wwwv0 800.0 0000.0 2800 09.00 9.080 .880 .8382 .880 083-82 88‘. .02.: 338. 03838 850 88.. 338... I: 3] sydgaaou N u— I ~ ~ 0m000 .830 00.0.0 omc. ‘0 0000.0 300.0 m0000 Emmu .03.. 883-803 80:38 :85 88:3... 8.8:. :93: 8088.98. 883 8:38.08. :88". 8:38... ..:w< ~l~l”|*l“l~°l*|°° @ISI h 0 m w m N . Emma 8889:. .03 803 80:38 :85 88:3 “. 8.8:... .83. 8038.qu 883 :o8:o.axm :88". 388.. 03:30:84: 8.3.>8< 8888:. 8:3..083nm 8.38038.— 0:3::::0:.xm 83:93. 208 lou 5191410 uuezyuefijo spldoad uouanpmd punoq ploqasnoH ssalpuel uouanpmd ploqssnoH =0:2:E:8< .239 5:28:50 1295 cozmflcumSO 9509 205820: 2:020ng 952. 305301 36:83; _ue mo UHSOm wig; EuEonEm conmzoixm wEEBm n.:=ouu< b.5252 euawouww< [nudeg [unleN Joqn p911“ ousawoq 19mg .280. . $236530 .8 8522.05 awash“ msocuwoucu we 5522 .mm 29; 209 210 88._ 88._ 88._ 88.. 88._ 88._ 88.. 33885 Bee 2 88._ 333285 8 @Nomd 3.53 05.3 and mm :6— .o EoEEo>oO vm 88.8 3&8 5:5: MN :oc-:E=8< 13:30 .8532 mm 5.588500 13850 .9382“ mwiéméuogmgfi d” @050on 8: £210 a. 88.8 3:; 883.35 $8884 258 29.3.8: 3285; q a 88.8 fiofisofifiufiqufl m 88.8 825 288.5: anaemm m. 88.8 88.. 8.83.8; 520533 3 $0.53 ozv N; ommod oooo._ ocmmd 2mmU w M82 .28 333-803 n 88.8 M: No 82:8 saodl wvmod vvood mar—0:2“— m 985 _on v 52.5038”; own? m mmm _ d conga—ax”; $20li 88.8 weigh. ..S..<.._l 0N mm VN mm NN 3.. ON m:_&=m EBB 82:80.50 3:95 =o_§=:_=oo< 22380300 mw5>am Bowen 2: go 3.9m 58:: 1295 .8382 3:93 .8332 bcogmgfi 3588< b.3282 o.auo..uu< 322$ mzocomoxm 3:an mean—Evans .38. . 82:86:35 5% $222882 owmb>a msocowowco mo x522 .mm 2an coo. p ooo. _. ooo. 08.0 ooo. w ooo. w ooo. _. 08. F .326... w :00 0~00 00.0 0~00 0.0.0 0~00 00.0 ..000 020.000.0000 0~ m. 000.0 :00 0000 R00 0.00 .000 000.0 0000 0:02. 2:330 0~ m 0....0 .000 ..000 000.0 0000 000.0 000.0 0.00 20550.60 0~ s 0~00 .000 00.0 0.00 ...00 .000 0.00 0~00 3.2.000 ~20 .000 08.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 0.00 300000050: 0~ 000.0 000.0 ~80 .000 .80 ~80 ~80 000.0 2.0320830800002m - .20 0~00 00.0 0~00 0.00 .80 000.0 ..000 co...0_oe%o_2aaoazm .~ 0000 ~80 0.00 .80 0.0.0 0~00 0.0.0 0~00 0003000005325: 0~ 000. 00.0 ~00. 0~0. 00.. 0~0. 0.4.0 000. 3.2.8.0 0.0.0 ..000 08.0 0000 0.0.0 300 0~00 000.0 00.0.8038 emsom 0. 00.. .000 .80 .80 -00 ~80 0.00 000.0 02.00.0005 0.200an 0. 00.0 0.00 .0..0 .0~.0 .0..0 080 00.0 00.0 00.2809. 000.003 m. 0. 000.0 .000 0000 ~00. ~000 0.... 000.0 0.0. 00.8000050205asmw ... 000.. 00.0 0.0.. .4.~. .~... ~00. 0:0 .00.. 32.80 000.0 000.0 ..000 .000 0000 000.0 000.0 0000 5.08.2202 0. m 0000 .000 000.0 000.0 .000 000.0 000.0 000.0 _0._08000&-002H~. .m 0000 .000 .000 000.0 ..000 0~00 000.0 000.0 .83 02.1.0. .. m 0~... 000.0 000.0 0~00 0~00 000.0 .000 0000 03880005800500 0. s .0..0 000.0 ..000 00... 000.. 08.. 000.0 00~. 303 0.60... 0 R- 00.. 0.0. 000.. 000.. -0. 0..~. .3. 3.2000 000.~ .80 ~80 0~00 0~00 $00 08.0 0000 .2000 0 000.0 ~00. 0.0.0 0000 000.0 0.00 ~.00 0.0.0 32033082, 0 0.00 0000 v8. 080 000.0 08.0 000.0 000.0 085020500 0 000.0 08.0 0.00 .0... 000.0 00.0 000.0 8.0 megawm 0 0~00 000.0 000.0 000.0 ~00. 20.0 .000 :00 0508:5500... v 080 000.0 000.0 ~..0 0000 .... 000.0 ~..0 .00§0.050000>>w 0 ..00 3.0 ....0 0.0.0 ...00 :00 0.0. :00 082.205.0200 ~ ~.0_0 08.0 ~80 0.00 000.0 0.00 -00 .00. 8.5.000? . 0 ~ 0 0 0 0 ~ . Sumo coaoauoa 08.:om 00:020.“. 9.69.0 .coE>o_aEw cozmzoaxm 0E5. .00. 082. .050 .200 0002. .003“. 82.809. 30:83.. 00_._>_.o< 02.2690. unocououcm 0.5.0000 0:0:0wox0 5,. 0020:0020 0w0.0>0 0:0 0.55000 0:0:0woucu .o 0.2 .0 x502 .VN 0300. 211 08.. 08.. 08.. 08.. 08.. .8280 3 .8 0 0.0.0 0~.0 000.0 0~00 3.0500008 0~ 0 am 080 08.0 0.00 000.0 030 0.53 0.0.0 .000 0~ w ~8 0 ~80 000.0 00.0 ~80 2.065200 0~ 0 :00 000.0 00~.0 000.0 0.00 .5280 08.0 08.0 0000 ~0~0 08.0 .5500 00:5: 0~ .8 0 .80 0~00 000.0 .8 0 800.558... .0800 .32 m. - 0 .80 0.0.0 0~.0 000.0 0~00 80052000 3.00032 m. .~ -00 0~00 0.00 000.0 -00 0003000500002. I 8 ...... .0.... 000.. 00~.~ 00.; .3280 000.0 .000 ~000 0.00 0000 000.800.820.00 m 0. :00 0.0.0 0.0.0 .00.. :00 803.000.000.080 m. 0. 0 00.0 000.0 ~80 .0~,0 ~0~0 m.09....009. 000.003 m. 0. E... 08.0 08.. 000 0 .0... 00.0.0002. 30.9...050 w 0. 000.. 000.. 0~0. .0~.~ 000.. .5280 08 . 000.0 08 0 08 0 08.0 .0008 .2202 0. m 08.0 08.. 080 08,0 08.0 .0008 0008-002 .... ~. ~ cm 08.0 080 .00 . .000 08.0 .000. 00.... m. .. w 0~00 0.0.0 000 0 000.. 0.0.0 0.2.0. 0000.80 .200 0 0. m 0.00 :00 00~0 00. 0 0.0.. .003 .0500 0 0000 ~000 000.0 000.. 000.0 0.2.80 -0 0 .~00 .0..0 0.0.. -00 3:00 0 08 0 08.0 0~00 ~00 0 08 0 .00. 0003-083 0 0.8 0 .000 0 .0 0 0 .0 0 08 0 08:50 .200 d 0 00. 0 3.0 000 0 ~00 0 8. 0 8:000". W 0 . :0 0 0000 000 0 0~00 080 0500.0 .500 m 0 0. .0 0~. 0 000 0 ~00 0 0. .0 2080.060 0003 w 0 0.0.0 0.00 0.00 0.00 :0 0 8036.000 .0200 ~ 0.0 0 000 0 000 0 0 .00 000 0 00:50,. :0< . 0. ~. .. 0. 0 .8500 .8500 .003 .00.... 0.2.... .003 3.60“. .9202 0.008-003. . 0500800 .050 . 0253000 00:02.90. .0 0.0.00”. naoaoeam ..:00. . 0.5.0000 0:0:0w0x0 .0.. 000.0500... 0w0.0>0 000 0.5.0000 000003.000 .0 m..>. .0 .0..0—2 .vm 030... 212 80.. 80.. 000.. 000.. 000.. 80.. 32.000 3 00. 0 0:0 000 0 08 0 000.0 0000 020.000.0000. 00 m 000.0 0.00 000.0 000.0 000.0 000 0 2.03 20.0 .03. 00 m 000 0 0.0 0 08.0 .000 000.0 000 0 20550.60 ..0 s 00. .0 .000 000.0 0.000 000.0 000.0 0.2.000 0.0.0 000 0 0000 08 0 :00 080 .3500 5:5: 00 000 0 000.0 .80 .00 0 0000 .00 0 800.0833. .506 002 .m 00 00. 0 0:00 000.0 0000 000 0 000.0 02.0.0230. .3500 .02 m .0 .00 0 .0. 0 080 0.0.0 0.0 0 .000 m0...0000020002._ 00 000.0 000.0 02.0 000.. 0.... 0. .... 39.000 0.0.. ...0 0 0000 0.0.0 0.0 0 000.0 000.02.. .2. 0.200 .u: 0. 000 0 000 0 .000 0.0 0 000 0 0.00 80025.05 0.208.. m. 0. 00. .0 00. .0 .000 000.. 00. .0 0000 00.2.0002. 08.2.3 m. 0. 0000 000 0 0000 000.0 0.00 .00 . 00.0080005220050 w z 00... 0:... 000.0 0.00 000.. .000 39.000 000 0 800 .000 80 0 000 0 000 0 3.08 .8202 0. m 0000 .00 0 ..00 0.00 08 0 0000 .0008 0005-002 ... 0. am 0000 000.0 000 0 08 0 000.0 000.0 .003 02... m. .. m 000 0 .00.. .00 0 0.0 0 ..00 0 000 0 0.2.... 202...... .200 0 0. s 000.. 00. .0 000.0 0. 0.0 0000 0. 0 0 .003 0.5.0. 0 000.. 000.. 000.. 000.0 000.. 80.0 39.000 0000 000 . .000 ...0 0 000 0 000 0 200.0 0 . .0 0 000 0 000 0 08 0 0. 0 0 0. 00 .20 0008-083 0 000 0 000 0 000 0 000 0 .000 0000 08.08 .200 d 0 000 0 0.0 0 0: 0 .0. 0 000 0 000 0 8.02.0.0 W 0 000 0 0.0 0 000 0 000 0 000 0 .00 0 0500.0 .85. m. 0 000 0 0.... 0 0000 .0. 0 0000 0. .0 0.05.2900. 0003 u 0 000 0 ...0 0 0... 0 000 0 000.0 0. .0 000000.000. .020. 0 000.0 0.00 00. 0 ..00 0000 2.00 052.0. :0... . 0. 0. 0. 0. 0. ... a. .0000 8:00.00... .... 0000 0.: .m:M.2..O 0.0.0.000. O 00.000. 29.0000... 000038.... .3102 0.0.0.500”: .00....020. 0.0.—53¢. 00.0.3.3... 0550 00.2.0027”.— 02050300. 000.0504 00.2.0039. 520.....05m m:OUS~Sm:_ naoaodoacm .000. . 0.5.0000 00.00.00.000 .0. 02.50.000.80. 00.0.30 0:0 0.5.0000 0:000w005 .0 0.5. .0 0.0.0.). ...m 0.0.0.. 2l3 83 83 83 88.. 3835' 3 :8 ES 83 3;. o 3.83838 0N m 83 £2 - 8w 0 283 05 we fix mN m 3N8 N: o - «8 o Eoeegoo «N m. 08.; 0N3 88.3 83 3835 N8 8 N2 o - Soc .253 58:: NN Soc 83 - N8 8 8.33833 3.98 .32 m NN :8 _S o 83 3% o 8.3.838 338 32 W _N z: .o «88 - NN3 mwsémussfii a EN 83 - 2% 398m :3. Eco - as o 398% 6: 925 m 2 23 3. ,_ - _ovo S=§§w5 $38.3 m N. a: .o x: 8o - E 8 £288; 3223‘. m. 2 2N8 83 - £3 £23.32 322=§m w I 23 :3 - :3. 328m 83 28 o - _8 o 3&3 3532 2 ma :8 o 28 o - N88 .958 028-52 H N_ .w @880 So o - N8 o .23 8:: m. : w 3N3. oNv _ - a: o 9:9: 0:828 350 a o. m 0N. .o .2 8o - 83 :53 35a”. 0 $3 RNN - 8N3 398m 8: 8 N - 80 o SEC w Omoc cmoc - _ _v o _03 “5336003 5 N88 zoo - 83 82:8 550 H 8 m8 0 as o - S. _o 8:25 m. m 23 as o - mNo o mag; .33 m. w :5 o 3.0 o - 25 o E05835 ems)» u N :o o _ _o o - 8_ o cozsaaxm aeé N N5 0 NS o - ”Noe 9.55“. 33 _ NN NN _N ON .3.an :o_3_:E:8< coaaaoaoo E2582: SEE: _nzanu .8332 .8.qu .9332 m.:=ouu< 3:39 «gang—...”.— .Eoo. . .8588 mzocowoxo .8 8222.05 ewfigw was 3.588 mzocowonco .8 32 mo x532 .vm 2an 214 C.2. Livelihood Activities of Households Table 25. Livelihood activites of households in five communities. wood charcoal production Primary Livelihood Activity Total Secondary Livelihood Total Tertiary Livelihood Total abaca production 7 abaca production 1 banana farming l carpentry 9 banana farming 3 carpentry 4 charcoal production 2 carpentry 8 coconut farming 4 coconut farming 72 charcoal production 3 community councilor 2 construction worker 2 charcoal trading 2 community security i cook 1 coconut farming 29 construction worker 1 corn farming 1 community security i cook 2 family subsidy l cook 1 electrician i farm caretaker 1 corn farming 1 fishing 5 fishing 3o fishing 7 hauling timber 4 forest farrnlng 4 handicraft 2 lowland farming 8 forestry l hired laborer 2 metal worker l forestry and lowland farming l Jeepney driver 2 no 255 government employee 1 jeepney operator T piggery l handicraft l lowland farming l2 renting house i hired farm labor 3 masonry 2 retail store 2 hired labor 6 no 187 retail store & bakery 1 ice cream 1 rattan trading 2 rice farming l jeepney conductor 1 renting 3 teacher 1 Jeepney driver 2 retail store 3 vines harvesting l Jeepney operator 1 retail trading 4 laundry 1 rice farming l 1 local councilor 2 timber harvesting i lowland farming 44 vegetable farming l masonry 2 vines harvesting 2 midwifery 1 white clay mining 6 na 50 rattan harvesting 3 rattan marketing 1 renting 2 retail store 1 retail trading 2 rice farming 21 timber harvesting l timber hauler 3 utility worker l vegetable farming 4 vines harvesting 1 white clay mining 2 l 215 C.3. Various Examples of Approaches to SAM Evaluation A number of approaches of evaluation result from examining the SAM. In Chapter 5, the focus of evaluation was on natural resources exploitation. Below are summary evaluation that pertain in general to community economic performance. Level of Dependence The variation of the level of contribution suggests a number of possible explanations. These include lack of capacity for other forms of production, or immobility or unavailability of some form of capital for production; ownership of factors of production, and possibly initial endowment or wealth. Table 26 shows that agriculture generates the most income for rural households. Total household-production value consists of 49% from agriculture, 27% from forestry (including fuelwood production and CBF M), and 23% percent from other livelihood that includes fishing, wage employment, retail trading and other small-scale livelihood activities. Therefore, households in five communities are more agriculture-intensive rather than forestry-intensive. The overall forest exploitation that includes community- based management program and fuelwood production a fourth of total production income in 1998, the survey year. It is important to note that the larger value in this forest production obtains from potential production that the CBFM reported (P 8,920,866 see 216 Table 12), instead of actual production and sale. Nonetheless, it provides potential information on the depreciation of natural resources. Table 26. Total value of production activities of the S communities. Production Activity Values (Pesos) Proportion Agricultural Farming 35,375,061 49% Forest Exploitation 6,905,719 10% Wage Employment 5077.387 7% Retail Trading 3.072.002 4% Fisheries 5.884294 8% Other sources 2,833,365 4% Wood-based fuel 3,582,927 5% CBFM 8,920,866 12% Total 71,65 1,622 100% Income Distribution On consumption of own-production, landless households have comparatively higher values for non-agriculture-based production, particularly fuelwood. Both household types showed no purchase of agriculture and forest products. Aggregate factor receipts of landless households were lower than small-holders considering that the landless comprise only 23% of total households. For consumption expenditures (market purchases), landless households import expenditures total 74% while small-holders total only 71% suggesting greater consumption of own-farm production by the latter. Logically, wage employment and purchases from fisheries output is relatively higher for landless households, due to lack of land to cultivate and produce agricultural crops for own-consumption, essentially relying on "free goods." 217 Self-sufficiency in Production Sufficiency of production output also suggests less significant import of consumption goods. In the constructed SAM, if imports of communities exceed exports, communities are net importers of consumption goods as a result of two possible scenarios. One scenario is that prices of production outputs compared to prices of consumption goods purchased outside of the community are considerably low. The other is that production technology cost is relatively higher, because of potentially higher imported input costs. The outcome remains that a considerable part of natural resource exploitation remains "un-transacted" in the market. Thus, an aspect of this evaluation that links natural resources and economic performance is to identify marketed or non- marketed outputs of production. in the five communities, non-traded output for aggregated household production was 23%. Total marketed component of all production output was 77%. The marketed component covers local purchases/sales and exports outside of the community. This is consistent with previous estimated figure of 25% of GNP by James (1996) for national accounts. A cursory analysis of forestry production by households reveals that 20% did not enter the market (direct household consumption and used for other purposes), the rest were sold outside of the community. Directly consumed forestry output considering the 218 whole community. that includes C BF M production, was 23%. This shows the increasing emphasis of household exploitation of natural resources for trade in the market, because of relatively high value-added relative to other production outputs. However, the significant value of non-traded output and consumption of own-production suggest less than full integration of the communities to the market; shadow prices diverge from market prices; and, transaction costs are ubiquitous. Subsistence production, significant divergence between shadow price and market price, and trade imbalances suggest that certain production outputs remain unrecorded in national accounts. In most instances, natural resources exploitation occurs but not recorded, hence, its condition remains undetermined. C.4. Valuation Approaches The value-added of forest resources harvested by household and POs involved with the CBFM program of the five communities was based on market value; that is the stumpage value of timber calculated as shown in Table 27. This represents the rent captured by the community in the exploitation of non-produced natural capital. CBF M output were basically priced at market value. However, value of timber harvested was based on residual stumpage price after costs of extraction were subtracted. 219 Table 27. Calculation of timber price (in Pesos) and proportion of cost components.a Percent of Pricing of timber harvest Value timber sales value Sales per bd ft 17.00 100.0% Reforestation l .00 5 .9% BEN RO/ Protection 1.00 5.9% Savings/Livelihood 1.00 5.9% Admin Cost 1.50 8.8% Chain saw operator 2.75 16.2% Slicing 1.50 8.8% Hauling 4.00 23.5% Forest Charges 2.50 14.7% Trucking 1.50 8.8% Miscellaneous expenses 0.25 1.5% Estimated timber rent or stumpage value 4.50 26.5% Estimated net export value 2.00 11.8% “ Based on the calculations by the C PEU lnc. officers in 1998. Depreciation value was based on the imputed value of natural capital used in production activities. The most widely used approach was stumpage valuation. Other valuation approaches for various commodities are described below: - Fuelwood consumed by households were either purchased from the market or directly consumed production outputs. There is a divergence of prices of fuelwood observed from responses to the survey. This is an indication of an imperfect market. Therefore, in calculating the value of wood fuel, market price of wood fuel in urban center or local market was used. Fuelwood valued using the wage rate, calculated as wage rate in the locality multiplied by the 220 number of hours spent on harvesting this product, proved to be higher that market price of fuelwood per unit. Thus, there is great divergence between the shadow price of fuelwood and its market price; Values in agriculture output were based on market prices; Family labor following the general valuation for all activities represent residual values after other factor value added were removed; Other forestry outputs were based on market price both for conventional factors of production and natural resource exploited; Wage employment values were based on local wage rates. Wage differences occurs in five communities; those closest to urban centers recorded higher wage rates; Retail trading values were based on market values; Fisheries output were based on market values, both locally sold or in urban centers; Other sources were valued at cost; and 221 Natural capital depreciation value was based on rent on natural resources, and computation differ for each activity. Household forestry activities were based on stumpage value in harvesting timber and non-timber forest resources. C BF M output were based on stumpage value after C BF M costs were removed. Costs component for each natural resource vary depending on the activity. Using common stumpage will overvalue some of natural resource outputs and undervalue some. For instance, the stumpage value for timber harvest by a household would differ from the stumpage value of that harvested by the CBFM, because cost components and technology employed in harvesting differ. 222 C.5. Simulation Runs with Varying Fire Occurrences and Optimal Level of Harvest Spreadsheet simulation made use data from the stand and stock table of the three POs at the Bicol National Park. The aggregate growing stock from these three tables was 540,196 cubic meters (yield per hectare multiplied by the total area of 3,290 hectares). This figure is the initial opening stock of timber in the simulation model. Closing stock was derived by deducting harvest, natural mortality and fire damages from the opening stock and adding in-growth from existing growing stand and new growth (regeneration) from opened areas. Table 28 presents various parameters used in the simulation model. Table 28. Parameters used in simulation. Variables/ Parameters Unit of Measure Values Market price of timber P/bd fi 17 Harvest damage values Abandoned logs % 3.75 Butt trimmings % 2.5 Stumps % 0.1 Residual damage % 50 Tops and branches % 33.75 Forest fire damage % 5.2 Harvest volume per hectare cu m/ha/yr 184.07 Initial opening stock cu m 540,196 Initial basal area cu m/ha 8.0 Initial Years elapsed afier logging years 25.0 Growth rate per hectare cu m/ha/yr 3.9 The growth function (Balangue, 1991) used to derived the growth was the Revilla model: Yield = 0.84288+O.40458*ln(BPO)+0.33674* In (YEAL)+0.46925* In (BPO)* In(S) 223 Where: BPO — dipterocarp basal area at YEAL = 0 YEAL — years elapsed after logging S — measure of site quality A number of simulation runs were done to evaluate various scenarios. Of particular significance to this study are: (1) Simulate stock trend at various levels of harvest expressed as hectares harvested, (2) opening and ending stock at 12 hectares of harvest and varying fire occurrences to present optimal level of harvest and (3) trends of stock based on the three harvest scenario discussed in Chapter 5. Table 29 presents stock scenario at various harvest levels. Table 30 presents simulation results that evaluates the harvest levels at various fire occurrences. Table 31 presents stock levels for three harvest scenarios discussed in Chapter 5. Figure 8 presents the trend of opening and closing stocks for three harvest options discussed in Chapter 5. Trend of site disturbances is also presented. 224 Table 29. Simulation trials with varying area harvested and fire occurrences. No. of Hectares Beginning Ending Difference Volume Freq of Trials Harvested Stock Stock Harvested Fires 1 74 540,196 194,999 345,197 13,621 1 2 73 540,196 173,931 366,265 13,437 1 3 60 540,196 273,901 266,295 1 1,044 1 4 50 540,196 349,700 190,496 9,204 0 5 49 540,196 328,715 211,481 9,019 l 6 48 540,196 334,752 205,444 8,835 1 7 46 540,196 329,643 210,553 8,467 2 8 45 540,196 374,982 165,214 8,283 0 9 44 540,196 390,125 150,071 8,099 O 10 42 540,196 351,502 188,694 7,731 2 1 1 41 540,196 353,250 186,946 7,547 2 12 40 540,196 377,563 162,633 7,363 1 13 39 540,196 385,516 154,680 7,179 1 14 38 540,196 419,980 120,216 6,995 0 15 37 540,196 345,840 194,356 6,81 1 3 16 36 540,196 404,991 135,205 6,627 1 17 35 540,196 412,416 127,780 6,442 1 18 34 540,196 441,953 98,243 6,258 0 19 33 540,196 452,949 87,247 6,074 0 20 32 540,196 400,897 139,299 5,890 2 21 31 540,196 457,860 82,336 5,706 0 22 30 540,196 464,448 75,748 5,522 0 23 29 540,196 444,439 95,757 5,338 l 24 28 540,196 424,292 1 1 5,904 5,1 54 2 25 27 540,196 431,334 108,862 4,970 2 26 26 540,196 416,490 123,706 4,786 3 27 25 540,196 470,551 69,645 4,602 1 28 24 540,196 502,506 37,690 4,418 0 29 23 540,196 452,107 88,089 4,234 2 30 22 540,196 486,551 53,645 4,050 1 31 21 540,196 464,095 76,101 3,865 2 32 20 540,196 468,51 1 71,685 3,681 2 33 19 540,196 529,338 10,858 3,497 0 34 18 540,196 536,617 3,579 3,313 0 35 17 540,196 540,835 -639 3,129 0 36 14 540,196 529,516 10,680 2,577 1 37 13 540,196 563,625 -23,429 2,393 0 38 12 540,196 544,371 -4,175 2,209 1 39 12 540,196 489,045 51,151 2,209 3 40 1 1 540,196 492,992 47,204 2,025 3 41 10 540,196 581,607 -41,411 1,841 0 225 Table 30. Simulation to determine the optimal level of harvest at varying fire occurrences. No. of No. of Beginning Ending . Volume Freq of Trials Hectares Stock 2 Stock 2 Difference Harvested Fires 1 12.00 540,196 572,188 -31,992 2,209 0 2 12.00 540,196 571,682 -31,486 2,209 O 3 12.00 540,196 571,114 -30.918 2,209 0 4 12.00 540,196 571,043 -30,847 2,209 0 5 12.00 540,196 570,128 -29,932 2,209 0 6 12.00 540,196 570,029 -29,833 2,209 0 7 12.00 540,196 569,901 -29,705 2,209 0 8 12.00 540,196 542,682 -2,486 2,209 1 9 12.00 540,196 542,108 -1,912 2,209 l 10 12.00 540,196 541,615 -1,419 2,209 1 1 1 12.00 540,196 541,088 -892 2,209 1 12 12.00 540,196 541,016 -820 2,209 1 13 12.00 540,196 540,827 -631 2,209 1 14 12.00 540,196 540,015 181 2,209 1 15 12.00 540,196 539,904 292 2,209 1 16 12.00 540,196 539,532 664 2,209 1 17 12.00 540,196 539,476 720 2,209 1 18 12.00 540,196 516,789 23,407 2,209 2 19 12.00 540,196 516,627 23,569 2,209 2 20 12.00 540.196 516.331 23,865 2,209 2 21 12.00 540,196 516,199 23,997 2,209 2 22 12.00 540,196 515,876 24,320 2,209 2 23 12.00 540,196 515,134 25,062 2,209 2 24 12.00 540,196 515,112 25,084 2,209 2 25 12.00 540,196 515,040 25,156 2,209 2 26 12.00 540,196 514,092 26,104 2,209 2 27 12.00 540,196 514,056 26,140 2,209 2 28 12.00 540,196 513,972 26,224 2,209 2 29 12.00 540,196 512,936 27,260 2,209 2 30 12.00 540,196 489,947 50,249 2,209 3 31 12.00 540,196 489.090 51.106 2,209 3 32 12.00 540.196 488,401 51,795 2,209 3 33 12.00 540,196 488,195 52,001 2,209 3 34 12.00 540,196 487,878 52,318 2,209 3 35 12.00 540,196 487,036 53,160 2,209 3 36 12.00 540,196 465,915 74,281 2,209 4 37 12.00 540,196 465,068 75,128 2,209 4 38 12.00 540,196 464,154 76,042 2,209 4 39 12.00 540,196 463,214 76,982 2,209 4 40 12.00 540,196 462,052 78,144 2,209 4 41 12.00 540,196 439,967 100,229 2,209 5 42 12.00 540,196 438,357 101,839 2,209 5 43 12.00 540,196 436,758 103,438 2,209 5 44 12.00 540,196 434,920 105,276 2,209 5 45 12.00 540,196 165,414 374,782 2,209 2 226 .. 8: N3 .2 an .82 28N N822 N28. 82.2... 88...... N228 84.82. on N o .E. 82 ..Nm an .82 8.x .E... 8 2.32 8.82. 238 88.2 ... .88 2. ..N o .... ... NN .2. EN .82 EN N .32 85.: N ... ......m 23.28 8N.NNN 88.8% .... MN 8 ...... 2.: 2... mmmN .82 .....N 88.88 832 38.8% 42.88 25.3 82% 2. NN o 8... ..NNN 8.. an .82 EN 42.88 ...38 82% SNNQ 8...: 83...... 8.. .N . «N4 ...MN .8 “RN .82- 8% 8N8“ 82.42 84......“ 84.8% 2.5% 88.88 2. ..N o E. .82 8 EN .82 82 82.5% 85.2 ..NNNNm 88.8% 28.8.. 48.88 .... 2 o 2... SN 2... mmmN .82 NE 88.8. 2.38 .8de 88.28 ....o...Nm 8:88 2. 2 o NmN 82 an 2.2 .82 :8 5.28 4.5.48 .58. .2..me 8.8.5. 822 N.. 2 .. ... 8m 8 an .82 85 45.8% 8.38 838 48...: 82.2 828 ... 8. o ..2. N8N 88 RN .82 .8... 48.88 82.2 82.2. 48.5 8.88 ..aNNmm .... 2 o 82 :2 8m 22 .82 ...: :22 88.88 42.88 28.82 22...: 2.8.88 2 ... o 88 2.: 8.. an .82 82 28.82 82.8 2.8.88 .828 42.88 8.82 ..N 2 o 8N. ..8 2. mmmN .82 an :38 42.8.. 84.88 8...... 8.3.3.. 3.88 8 N. .. SN 2.... am an .82 82 88...? 83.2. 2.28 N382 2.2... 22.8 3 : o 2.. .NNN 2.. WEN .82 82.. 2.8.28 82... 22.2 N882 2.8.2. 8.....2 mm o. o 8 8m 8. an .82 8.... NNNfim 2.8.. 2. 82......“ E. . a ..N.2... 2.88 ..m a o 8.. EN ...: an .82 8.... E. . a ..N.2... 2.98 88.28 .882. 23.88 2 w o 8.. 8: 2.8 an .82 2.... 88.82 3382. 23.82. 2.8.2.8 2.5:. 88.82 NM N o 2 ..2 2 2.2 .82 :2. 2.8.2.. 3.2.. 8.88 88...... 82...... 83mm .... 8 o N.. 8NN 8 an .82 8:... 82...... 82...... 832 58% 832. 2.32 ..m m o 3.. NmmN 2.. EN .82 2.... 88... 832. 2.32 2...“: 82.2.8 88.8 8N .. o ...m ....NN 88 22 .82 ..2... 2......“ 82.88 88.8 8.2.. 82...: 8N8. ..N m o ... N .2. .8 EN .82 ..2... 8.2.8 8...... 38mm 88. . ... 8.....88 28.88 NN N o .2 2K aNN mNmN .82 ....... 8a.... 8.....on 2...on 82...... 82...: 82...... 8N . H m m. m N ow N M N H H H m D .8. D N. D W H M 9 m A A mm m. Wm mm m m M mm. mm. mm mm .3 mm a m ...... mm mm mm m N. ... a... a... no... he 8.... m... w ... 0 .... Ce 7.. .l 0 1 p. __ 9 N C. Z l. D. 23:... .8 368m ,.o @620 can chugo .0.. S: coca—25m ,.o 28:65 .3 2an 227 62:82.. 88 E... .2853 .33.... 025 .8 :85 3.8.0 2... wESnO ,.o 2.2% .m 8%:— 228 23> RuwmumuuezSSL 33> [I F p p h u b p _ _ p b p P p _ p p h h p n h p o z z t L L L ao.<_u~o._. 9 7w 6 9 8 0 I. .7 Ir MG05<_O~OF It... i l “““ Tcom M- . . . _ . N . . p . . . . p p p p . . . . . . 2 r COO.MPM I I Fwo.<_28.+ . m m xooaw 9.60 0 it: 2 1 Y 8°de 8.. P w m .605 as: Olol . . 8°83 m. 83 m raw 25.88 m I . B 83.. w # g 8.. 88 u m P {w , a 08.03" W. 83 u f .. . . [1, 833 n . B .. 58.8... m . o8 N 8°83 83 o8.o$ 59.0“. 526.0 ucoomw No 3.2 30... «552.331 coo; 83.552 33> Z Z l l w..wl0> L mNNN.N2tm.9:aNmN. 9 Z 6 9 8 0 I. v t . .......L...r+y..........rO ...p......L|r»..»...._.... 00°C”? 286 286+ 1 ; 1 - . I. Nxoow 05:08 LI \1 f 80.2: m. wwxwwomwowflnwm‘w IT. 000 CG? m m J.” Sodom M 838 . m / ./ ooo 88 ml . n . 82.8 m ooo own m 833 A... ooodmm m n , 838 M 1.5.! ooo own M Sodom ooo com .82»... .388... 2.8.2.8 5.3 .85... comoaen. 31293 02112 3