‘91". 1 gr». :5. in 1.552. . is, . s... ‘ J? was .35 19“. «F? a. u. 3., ‘ . n: .= :15 .3: u. .2! a 15...}... . . Z... . ,5 3...: .. 5.1. 5.13:1: ‘ I .v.\\uu1 v (v .u. 11:! I... EWEE. V . 7 . . . . . . I . .. a l ‘ i. 1.. A . , . H . . , an. . n r ' 1.2. 2. ‘ luau“; u .rbfiefi:\«o\ .11. , magnum WY. .1331 ofi.‘ U . , . u . 1‘ ll Init: C ‘ 3 I | 1 - ‘ I II! D llBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled "The Stock Market Returns to Disaggregated Intangible Investments" presented by Stephen B. Marasco has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph . D . degree in Economics wb‘gflgfih Major professor Date 0 2 a MS U is an Affirmative Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0-12771 PLACE IN RETURN BOX to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE DATE DUE DATE DUE 6/01 c-JCIRC/DateDuepss-p. 15 THE STOCK MARKET RETURNS TO DISAGGREGATED INTANGIBLE INVESTMENTS By Stephen B. Marasco A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2001 ABSTRACT THE STOCK MARKET RETURNS TO DISAGGREGATED INTANGIBLE INVESTMENTS By Stephen B. Marasco Innovative activity, particularly research and development, have public good characteristics that prevent firms from appropriating the full returns of their efforts, and thus firms under-invest in innovative activity. This argument has been used as a basis for implementing a number of government policies designed to stimulate investment in intangible assets. However, one could argue that these policies have been limited in their effectiveness because many aspects of the process of innovation remain poorly understood. This paper seeks to determine the relative profitability to firms of tangible and intangible assets, and the effect of firm size on the values of each. Intangible assets consist of knowledge stock, represented by research and development expenditures, and marketing stock, represented by advertising expenditures. The value of these intangible assets are determined using a stock market valuation approach. In addition to aggregate R&D, I examine the value of various types of R&D, including product, process, applied, and basic research, and test for potential interactions between product and process R&D. I find that intangible assets are more highly valued than tangible assets, but the value of different types of intangible assets varies widely. In general, the market places more value on R&D types lying closer to the output end of the innovation process, such as applied R&D and product R&D. Investments associated with the beginning of the innovation process, such as basic research, are not highly valued by the market. In addition, I find that the value of product R&D and process R&D are complementary. In other words, the effect of apprOpriability spillovers is stronger than any impact from potential organizational design trade-offs. Finally, I find support for an “appropriability effect” in which the value of process R&D increases more rapidly with firm size than the value of product R&D. C0pyright by STEPHEN B. MARASCO 2001 To my parents, Peter J. Marasco And Helen Kimball, And to my wife, Arlene ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The completion of my dissertation would not have been possible without the assistance of my dissertation committee. The Chair of my committee, Professor Kenneth Boyer, provided me with invaluable advice, encouragement, and patience from the beginning of the process to the end. His insights and attention to detail greatly improved the quality of my dissertation. Professor Bruce Allen offered helpful comments throughout many stages of the dissertation, and Professor Lisa George’s insights into the empirical analysis were extremely helpful. The insightful and intuitive comments of Professor Roger Calantone added depth to the final narration of my dissertation. Numerous people helped me at different stages of my Ph.D. program. My gratitude goes to the professors in the Economics Department for their guidance and instruction, and to my fellow Ph.D. students for their fi'iendship and support. I would particularly like to thank Industrial Research Institute/Center for Innovation Management Studies for the use of their unique data. I also would like to thank my co-workers at the House Fiscal Agency of the State of Michigan and Household International for their support and encouragement, and for providing me the opportunity to use my formal education in a professional setting, which in turn greatly added to the quality of my dissertation and afforded me the resources to see my work through to its completion. Finally, I would like to thank my family for their support. My deepest gratitude goes to my wife, Arlene Castellanos, for her faith, encouragement, and patience. This dissertation would not have been possible without her. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES IX LIST OF FIGURES X INTRODUCTION 1 1. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE 8 A. PRODUCT, PROCESS, AND OTHER TYPES OF INNOVATION ................................................................. 8 B. PRODUCT AND PROCESS INNOVATION WITHIN AN ORGANIZATION .................................................. 16 C. RETURNS To INNOVATION ............................................................................................................... 23 I. Determinants .............................................................................................................................. 23 2. Measurement .............................................................................................................................. 29 II. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND MODEL 39 A. INTERACTIONS BETWEEN PRODUCT AND PROCESS INNOVATION ..................................................... 40 B. THE MODEL ..................................................................................................................................... 44 C. SUMMATION OF HYPOTHESES/PROPOSITIONS .................................................................................. 66 III. EMPIRICAL FORMULATION AND RESULTS 67 A. DATA ............................................................................................................................................... 67 B. ESTIMATION AND RESULTS .............................................................................................................. 75 1. Empirical Framework ................................................................................................................ 75 2. Preliminary Analysis .................................................................................................................. 83 3. Appropriability Efi‘ect ................................................................................................................. 91 4. Interaction Between Product and Process R&D ........................................................................ 98 5. Unobserved Heterogeneity ....................................................................................................... 106 vii SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 109 APPENDICES 1 1 5 APPENDIX A 116 APPENDIX B 118 APPENDIX C 122 APPENDIX D 136 APPENDIX E 138 REFERENCES 140 viii LIST OF TABLES Table 1. Summary Statistics: Before Independent Variable Based Exclusions ($MM).. 72 Table 2a. Summary Statistics — Sample Data afier Exclusions (SMM) ........................... 73 Table 2b. Summary Statistics by Year-Sample Data (SMM) .......................................... 74 Table 3. Value of Aggregate Assets ................................................................................. 86 Table 4. Value of Disaggregated Intangible Assets ......................................................... 90 Table 5. Value of Disaggregated Assets Controlling for Firm Size ................................ 95 Table 5b. Stock Response at the Mean — Weighted Regression ...................................... 96 Table 6. Value of Aggregate Assets, Controlling for Firm Size ...................................... 97 Table 6b. Stock Response at the Mean — Weighted Regression ...................................... 98 Table 7a. Interaction Between Product R&D and Process R&D ................................... 101 Table 7b. Stock Response at the Mean — Weighted Regression .................................... 102 Table 7c. Interaction Between Product R&D and Process R&D, Controlling for Firm Size ................................................................................................................................. 104 Table 7d. Stock Response at the Mean - Weighted Regression .................................... 105 ix LIST OF FIGURES Figure 1. Relationship between revenue, cost, and R&D expenditures. .......................... 51 Figure 2. Relationship between R&D profit and R&D expenditures. ............................. 52 Figure 3. Relationship between marginal revenue and marginal cost. ............................ 55 Figure 4. Relationship between marginal net revenue (profit) and ex ante sales for each type of R&D assuming all parameters except h equivalent in each dimension. ....... 58 Figure 5. Relationship between optimal (profit maximizing) R&D expenditures and ex ante sales. .................................................................................................................. 60 Figure 6. Optimal allocation strategy with respect to sales. ............................................ 61 INTRODUCTION Technical innovation is a crucial input to economic growth and as such is a primary target for public policy designed to enhance national, state, and/or local innovation performance.‘ However, one could argue that these policies have been limited in their effectiveness because many aspects of the process of innovation remain poorly understood. Until recently, the majority of research on innovation has been focused on macroeconomic or industry effects, arguably at the expense of research aimed at the firm or business unit level. Accordingly, this study builds upon a relatively new and growing body of literature that investigates innovation at or below the firm level. Specifically, it examines the relative profitability to individual firms of different types of research and development expenditures and the value of alternative R&D resource allocation strategies. Economists long have recognized the important link between technological change and economic growth, although the modern investigation of this topic can be traced to Joseph Schumpeter (1942).2 Schmnpeter hypothesized that only firms in non- perfectly competitive industries would be able to innovate and create the technological change necessary for economic growth. In his view, technological change could only be attained once firms grew large enough to raise prices above their competitive level and ' Examples include the Federal Research and Experimentation tax credit, the patent system, and numerous state and local tax and investment credits. For a discussion of the influence of government policies on innovation, see Horwitz (1979) and Hollomon (1979). 2 Early references to the importance of technical change include Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations (1776) and David Ricardo’s 0n the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation (1817). gain economic profits — profits that could then be used to invest in technical research and development. The idea that firm size and technological change are related has become known as the Schumpeter hypothesis. Although much effort has been devoted to investigating the validity of Schumpeter’s hypothesis, today researchers are faced with the hard truth that the relationship between market structure, firm size, and technological change is not nearly as clear-cut as Schumpeter originally hypothesized. In addition to firm size, other industry and firm characteristics play an important role in innovative activity.3 Not surprisingly, the relationship between R&D and innovation has received a considerable amount of attention in the literature. There is little doubt a strong link exists between R&D and successful innovation, but thus far, empirical efforts to quantify this link have been varied in both method and result. The reasons for this are several. First, the true nature of the relationship between profit and R&D, be it linear, quadratic, or some other form, is not known with certainty. Second, long lags ofien exist between R&D investment and the realization of the returns from R&D. The lag introduces uncertainty in the appropriate specification of the model, and disqualifies many sources of data that are not long enough to cover the appropriate time span. Third, a significant lag time between action and the observation of results limits the firm or policy maker’s 3 Examples include (1) the level of technological opportunities in the industry, (2) the appropriability conditions in the industry, (3) sunk costs in the status quo, and (4) the stage of the product life cycle. At the firm level, (5) the degree of interface between customer demand and the R&D department, (6) organizational design, and (7) applied R&D expenditures. See Acs and Audretch (1987), Scherer and Ross (1990), Hayes and Wheelwright (1984), and Utterback ( 1994). use of the relationship as a tool for planning. Another potential problem to measuring the returns to R&D lies in determining the correct proxy for innovation. That is, the composition of R&D with respect to product, process, or other types of R&D may by as important in determining the returns to innovation as the aggregate amount of R&D. Unfortunately, severe data cOnstraints have limited empirical efforts to decompose total R&D into reliable measures of product, process, or other types of R&D. From an empirical standpoint, the approach to measuring the returns to R&D taken in this study avoids many of these issues. This method, known as stock market valuation, relates R&D spending to the value placed on a firm’s assets by financial markets. It leverages the idea that publicly traded corporations are bundles of assets (such as R&D spending, advertising, and tangible assets) by incorporating these assets directly into the valuation equation. Therefore, it is particularly well suited to measuring the value of intangible assets. This method also allows a great deal of flexibility in terms of data structure and hypothesis specification. Multiple types of R&D may be regressed against market value, thus enabling the relative value to the firm of each type of R&D to be determined. The approach can also be used to determine if the returns from one type of R&D are significantly affected by an increase in returns from the other. Recent studies using a stock market valuation approach include Hall (1993) and Doyle (1994). Awareness that the composition of R&D is important to firm value is growing. Recent studies have indicated that some degree of success in both product and process innovation is necessary for a firm to be successful over the long term (Capon et. al., 1992). However, product and process R&D may not be equally valuable for all firms or completely independent of each other within firms. Cohen and Klepper (1996) suggest that larger firms benefit more fi'om process innovation than from product innovation. They also suggest that external factors, such as market conditions, can lead to positive appropriability interactions between product and process R&D. Athey and Schmutzler (1995) suggest that long-run organizational design factors such as ‘flexibility’ may contribute to ‘complementarities’ (i.e. positive extemalities) between product and process innovation that enhance the overall innovativeness of the firm and thus its long-run competitiveness.4 Yet, conventional wisdom suggests that firms have difficulty maintaining their efficiency in both product R&D and process R&D simultaneously over an extended period. This is sometimes referred to as a “trade-off” between product and process innovation. A 1993 article in Harvard Business Review is typical of this viewpoint. “.... either/or dichotomies dictated most managerial choices. A company could pursue a strategy of providing large volumes of standardized goods ‘ The term flexibility has been used in the economics literature to refer to a variety of concepts, although some of these concepts are closely related. For example, Moroni (1992) describes what he terms ‘production flexibility’, which he vaguely defines as the capacity of the firm to adjust to variations in external conditions. This definition of flexibility encompasses ‘strategic flexibility’, such as "the ability to Change production processes, production elements endowments and the qualities of outputs in relation to Changes in environmental conditions" (p. 168). It also includes the concept of ‘operational flexibility’, Which "is related to the possibility of varying the quantities produced within a given mix, using a given PTOductive structure.” (p. 168). or services at low cost, or it could decide to make customized or highly differentiated products in smaller volumes at a high cost. In other words, companies had to choose between being efficient mass producers and being innovative specialty businesses. Quality and low cost and customization and low cost were assumed to be trade—offs.” (Pine, et. al., p.111) In this instance, U.S. automobile makers, in response to Japanese competition, adopted a variety of new organizational designs in an effort to overcome this trade-off and improve their competitiveness. To an extent, these designs, such as product teams, were successful; but they also created other problems, “Cross-functional coordination has improved, but at the cost of depth of knowledge within functions.” (Sobek et. al, p. 37). Anecdotal evidence of this apparent trade-off between success in one type of innovative effort and another abound. General Motors, IBM, Xerox, and Motorola, to name a few, have had technologically superior products in the past. However, despite their great size and obvious market power, each has had its ability to create or leverage innovative and technologically competitive products questioned (Chesbrough and Teece, 1996) In addition to the research noted above, the potential for infra-firm interactions is reflected in the management science and organizational theory literature. This school of thought puts more faith in the notion of trade-offs than complementarities because they tend to view the firm as a complex, multi-function organization, rather than as a profit maximizing entity.5 In general, theories of the firm other than the standard neoclassical economics viewpoint allow much more room for intra-firm interactions and sub- optimizing behavior. Unfortunately, few theoretical models have been developed that account for the distinction between product innovation and process innovation. Of these, most tend to focus on the relationship between ex-post complementarities associated with appropriability and firm behavior. They generally ignore any factors that might impose constraints on firm behavior.6 In chapter 2, a theory of R&D allocation is developed that takes into account organizational constraints and market conditions that can form the basis for interactions between product innovation and process innovation. The efficiency of overall R&D may be affected positively, negatively, or not at all by these interactions. In chapter 3, using a relatively new set of data, the contribution of R&D composition to firm profitability is investigated empirically. In particular, the relative value of product R&D and process R&D is examined, along with an investigation of the potential for interactions between product and process R&D. In summary, the ability to measure the returns to different types of R&D will provide new insights into how the allocation of innovative resources affect an organization’s profits and equity values, and how outside factors may influence these 5 Theories of the firm other than the standard neoclassical theory include contractual relationship theory, principal-agent relationship theory, decision theory, etc. See Tirole (1990). 6 For example, Cohen and Klepper (1995) devise a model whereby firms choose to invest in product or process innovation based solely on profit incentives. They find that these incentives are complementary, but fail to consider the possibility of constraints in the firm’s maximization problem. Klepper (1996) develops a model of product and process R&D based on this same incentive principle to explain many of the stylized facts of the PLC. It works rather well, but is too general to be useful from a policy perspective. choices. The results of these inquiries can lead to improved R&D allocations by improving the information upon which the organization bases its R&D decisions. The results also will be a step forward in the quest to improve public policy towards R&D by providing policy makers with a better understanding of the determinants of firm innovativeness. For instance, one might argue that the R&D tax credit, depending upon how it is structured, benefits one type of R&D more than another, resulting in a sub- optimal allocation of R&D resources. Thus, a better understanding of the relative value of different types of R&D and the different conditions favoring each type would lead to a more efficient structure for the R&D tax credit. The study is organized as follows. The review of the literature is presented in chapter I. Chapter 11 contains a theoretical framework and model for R&D allocation. Data, empirical specifications, and empirical results are contained in Chapter III. A summary of results and some opportunities for further research are presented in the Conclusion. 1. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE Innovation has been defined as “an idea, practice or a material artifact perceived to be new by the relevant unit of adoption” (Zaltrnan et al. 1973, p. 10) and “... the search for and the discovery, development, improvement, adoption and commercialization of new processes, products, and organizational designs and procedures” (Jorde and Teece, 1992).7 This chapter presents a review of the literature on innovation, with a focus on research pertaining to conditions, behaviors, and structures that influence firm-specific innovation performance and value. I will discuss product, process, and other types of innovation and the influences of firm organization on the performance of each. Throughout this section I discuss the implications for innovation performance and behavior at the firm level. Finally, I discuss the returns to innovation in terms of determinants and measurement issues. A. Product, Process, and Other Types of Innovation Generally, product innovations affect the demand curve and process innovations affect the supply curve. Lee and Stone (1992) find that higher product R&D in an industry is correlated with higher price levels in the industry, while higher process R&D leads to 7 Innovation and invention are often confused. Innovation is a much broader concept - one that encompasses fire entire process of developing a new product or process and bringing it to market. Invention is critical but it is merely one facet of the entire innovation process. Scherer and Ross (1990) define invention as the “act of insight by which a new and promising technical possibility is worked out...” (p. 616). lower overall prices. More formally, product innovation has been defined in terms of any new product introduced by the organization (Knight 1967), or more broadly as any emerging technology or combination of technologies (Utterback and Abernathy, 1975). Tomatsky (1983) extends these to apply to any of the above that are exploited to produce goods for consumption. Process innovation, on the other hand, has been defined as “any operations technology that is new to the adopting organization,” (Collins et. al., 1988, p. 1) or “a change in the way products are made or deliver ” (T ushman and Nadler, 1986, p. 76). A broader definition put forth by Knight (1967, p. 482) defines process innovation as the “introduction of new elements in the organization’s task, decision, and information system or its physical production or service operations.” The idea that a product innovation affects the demand curve implies that the intent of a product innovation is to achieve two related goals: (I) retain or increase market share (either by introducing a new product or improving an existing one) and (2) widen the price- cost margin by increasing the price (value) of an existing product or create value by introducing a new product. By extension, any change to a product that results in no new market share nor the ability to raise prices, all things being equal, can not truly be considered a commercial product innovation (at least not a successful one). In other words, one must apply the following litmus test; if one holds market share constant, does the innovation allow the firm to increase price? Alternatively, will demand for the product increase while price is held constant? If the answer to either question is yes, then the innovation can be considered a product innovation. Again, the definition of a process innovation typically is dependent upon how it affects supply. For instance, Kanrien and Schwartz (1982) define process innovation within the context of productivity increases. They state that contributions to increases in productivity over time arising from technical change can be associated with shifts in the production function. Therefore, process innovations are specifically designed to increase the price-cost margin of a product by lowering the costs associated with production, via improved manufacturing techniques and/or equipment (of course, lower costs also may contribute to increased market share). However, the above definitions of product innovation and process innovation are inadequate in many respects. Most innovations display characteristics of both. Therefore, all innovations can be viewed as existing on a continuum with a pure product innovation at one extreme and a pure process innovation at the other, with most innovations lying somewhere in between. For instance, a given innovation could be viewed as a product innovation by the firm that created it, but a process innovation by a downstream firm that uses it in its manufacturing process. Consumers of the innovation (the downstream firm in this example) can decrease their costs and increase their productivity by using the new or improved good. Producers of the innovation increase their demand and obtain higher profits. In this case, an innovation displays characteristics of both a process innovation and a product irmovation depending on who benefits from it. In general, most product innovations, with exceptions such as consumer goods, can be considered someone else’s process innovation. Another illustration of the difficulty of classifying innovations as product or process 10 is the case of a product improvement not only increasing the demand for the product, but also simultaneously becoming easier to manufacture than the earlier version. This would both increase the value of the product and decrease its production costs, thereby exhibiting characteristics of both a product innovation and a process innovation as viewed by a single firm. Conversely, a process innovation may simultaneously reduce the manufacturing costs of a product, improve its quality, and ultimately increase demand. In either case, unlike the previous example, the same innovation is affecting a demand and supply curve in the same market. Therefore, most innovations affect a demand curve and a supply curve either within the same market or in two or more markets. Bhoovaraghavan et. a1. (1996) attempt to address these definitional issues by classifying product and process innovation in terms of consumer choice rather than in terms of supply side/resource allocation. In their view, an innovation is classified as product or process based on the perception of the consumer towards the innovation in relation to an already established product(s) that satisfies the consurner’s “core want”. The classification of innovation depends upon the additional wants that are satisfied by the new product that were not satisfied by the already existing product(s). “Process innovations are always perceived by the consumer as products that cater to or supplement only existing core wants. Product innovations are perceived by the consumer to be products that either cater to a new core want or supplement existing core wants.” (p. 237). Unfortunately, these definitions allow much room for interpretation and still place any innovation on the continuum somewhere between a pure product innovation and a pure process innovation. Despite the issues with definitions, there are several reasons why drawing a 11 distinction between process and product innovation can be useful. First, studying how firms allocate innovation-related resources provides insight into what industry deems important. Second, product and process irmovations, from a macroecononric perspective, affect the economy in different ways. For example, Japan’s economic emergence has been attributed in large part to its focus on process innovation, in contrast to the United State's focus on product innovation (Mansfield, 1988). Third, product innovations are the basis for the creation of new markets.8 In contrast, process innovations are usually created with the intent to increase productivity, lower costs, and/or redirect existing demand to different producers. The distinction also helps shed light on strategic interactions among firms. Product innovations are associated with innovative spillovers. Once a product is sold, the innovation is much more difficult to keep from being imitated, even with patent protection. Conversely, process innovations are easier to keep within the firm (Cohen and Klepper, 1998). Product and process are not the only possible innovation distinctions. Another useful distinction can be made between input and output innovation investments. Input investments include research and development (R&D), physical capital, and any investments undertaken before the innovation is ready for sale. Output investments are those that are intended to facilitate the sale of the innovation once it is at or near its final form. These include advertising, patents, liquidity, legal fees, distribution networks, sales forces, etc. Although much attention is paid to R&D, some estimate as much as half or 8 New technological trajectories are an important example of this. See CED (1980). 12 more of the total investment needed for a successful (profitable) innovation usually comes after the completion of the R&D efi‘ort (CED, 1980). In other words, an input investment will determine the ex-ante capability to generate an innovation whereas an output investment will increase appropriability, i.e., enhance the ex-post capability to profit from an innovation once it has been created. Bernstein (1986) incorporates the distinction between input and output investments by decomposing the production function of the firm into three primary inputs: labor, physical capital, and formal R&D. He analyzes the relationship between these inputs in the innovation process and finds two main effects. First, he finds a “substitution” effect among the inputs such that physical capital and R&D are complements, whereas labor is a substitute for the other two. In other words, ceteris paribus, an increase in the expenditure on physical capital also increases the expenditure on R&D, and vice versa, but reduces that of labor. However, increases in inputs presumably lead to increases in output as well, and thus demand increases for all inputs, including labor. He identifies this as the “output” effect. Essentially, there are complementarities (positive interactions) between input investments and output investments. Innovation-related investment also can be classified as tangible (physical) or intangible. Intangible investment is usually firm specific, such as organizational design, management, firm culture, knowledge, reputation, and informal R&D. A growing literature indicates that intangible capital may play a disproportionately large role in high technology and start-up firms, and is a growing proportion of corporate R&D (Crawford, 1991). This could be attributed to the fact that start-up firms in general do not have the financial l3 resources of larger, more established firms, and are forced to develop other strategies to compete, such as a heavier reliance on superior technology or superior management. Still another reason that firms may be becoming more intangible could be that technology itself is becoming less physical capital intensive and more information oriented (computers, software, intemet, etc.).9 Innovative activity is categorized ofien as basic research or applied research. Basic research can be defined as “original investigations that advance scientific knowledge but do not have specific commercial objectives, although such investigations may be in fields of present or potential interest to the company” (IRI/CIMS survey documentation, 1999). Applied research can be defined as “Investigations directed to the discovery of new scientific knowledge having specific commercial objectives with respect to products, processes or services” (IRI/CIMS survey documentation, 1999). An innovative firm undertakes both types of research to remain competitive. Finally, innovative activity, particularly R&D, often is classified as internal or external. Internal innovation is research and development performed in-house, whereas external innovation is outsourced. External R&D can take the form of research joint ventures, purchased R&D, purchased technology, patent purchasing and licensing, limited partnerships, and certain mergers and acquisitions. Crawford (1991) suggests that technology/knowledge gathered outside the firm is a growing proportion of total R&D. 9 R&D in general commonly is referred to as intangible, although here I am using the term to differentiate R&D itself. 14 Mowery (1994) also provides evidence that external R&D is growing in importance.10 Given the apparent growing importance of external R&D, treatments of external R&D issues have not been prominent in the literature. Exceptions are Audretsch et. a1. (1996) who analyze a data set fi'om a survey of Dutch manufacturing firms. The firms were asked to report whether or not they had conducted external R&D during a specified year (1983). Unfortunately, the amount of external R&D and the type, product or process, was not specified. A probit model was used to compare the frequency of external R&D to a variety of independent variables, such as firm size, capital intensity, skilled labor, amount of total R&D, etc. They find that capital intensity (positively) and skilled labor (negatively) were significantly correlated with external R&D. They explain their findings by theorizing that a high level of ‘asset specificity’, in this case labor assets (researchers and scientists), tends to increase the value of internal R&D but not that of external R&D. On the other hand, “a highly capital intensive firm will tend to produce a relatively standardized product, which can only be copied with great difficulty by another firm. Thus, ceteris paribus, external R&D is expected to be more prevalent in firms which are capital intensive.” (p. 521). This explanation is consistent with Bernstein’s ( 1986) results that showed a complementary relationship between physical capital '° The changing nature of technology itself may contribute to the ability of firms to find compatible external R&D. Information technology (computer design, faxes, intemet, and e-mail), decreasing barriers to transportation (lighter materials, faster transport, etc.), and other technologies are giving firms access to a larger pool of potential research partners. 15 accumulation and R&D investment, a significant portion of which, in light of the results reported by Audretsch et. al., may consist of external R&D.“ B. Product and Process Innovation within an Organization Do factors other than profit maximization, such as organizational design constraints, influence the returns to R&D? In general, the standard neoclassical viewpoint of the firm does not allow for intra-firm interactions and sub-optimizing behavior. Other, less restrictive, viewpoints allow a variety of factors to affect the R&D allocation decision and to depart from an exclusive focus on profit maximization. As Athey and Stern (1998) point out, the objective function faced by the agent responsible for R&D decision making is not necessarily limited to the overall economic profits of the firm. If one views the firm as a bureaucratic organization, with all of an organization’s complex interactions, then there are several theoretical reasons to believe extemalities may exist between product and process R&D. Athey and Schmutzler (1995) suggest that long-run organizational design factors such as “flexibility” (in either the product or the process dimension) may contribute to complementarities between dimensions that enhance the innovativeness of the firm and thus its long-run competitiveness.” They ” Gompers and Lerner (1998) suggest that corporate investments in venture-type endeavors can be nearly as successful as private venture capital projects provided they are strategically aligned with the parent company. They find these strategic investments stable over time, which is consistent with the theory that firms use external R&D to address structural shortcomings in their internal R&D program. '2 See footnote 4. l6 develop a two-period decision model. In the first period a firm chooses its ability to generate innovations, or in their language, chooses product and process flexibility and physical research capabilities. In the second period the firm takes these as given and maximizes profit by choosing a degree of innovative intensity in both dimensions. Their results suggest that there are complementarities in the innovation process that. manifest themselves in three particular ways: complementarities between dimensions in the short- run resource allocation decisions, complementarities between dimensions in the long-run capability decisions, and complementarities between the long-run and the short-rim decisions. Although Athey and Schmutzler support the idea of a positive interaction between product and process innovation, management theory offers some support to the idea that trade-offs, not complementarities, characterize the relationship between product and process innovation. This opposing position is based on the belief that the complexity of the firm necessitates compromises among multiple organizational fimctions, typically characterized as engineering, marketing, and manufacturing (Clark and Wheelwright, 1993, p. 161). Likewise, Volderba (1998) and Teece et. a1. (1997) suggest the firm is composed of a spectrum of ‘capabilities’. Chesbrough and Teece (1996) stress the importance of balancing the benefits of centralization against the potential rewards from risk-taking, which over-centralization can undermine. The idea of the firm as a bureaucratic organization also is common in principle— agent and contractual relationship lines of research. In this spirit, allocation decisions between product and process innovation can be viewed as a function of organizational l7 design. Organizational design is a term that encompasses the administrative and management structure of the firm (how decisions are made), the manufacturing system (e. g. “continuous process improvement” strategies and “teams”), the extent and structure of the distribution network, incentive packages, etc. Organizational design determines how physical capital is used and is an intangible asset (whereas research facilities, equipment, and personnel are tangible in nature). Hayes et. al., (1988) point out that flexibility in the manufacturing process is important to the long-term survival of the firm, but that within the firm there may be trade-offs between product flexibility and process flexibility. Utterback (1979), echoes this idea, “... conditions necessary for rapid (product) innovation are much different from those required for high levels of output and efficiency in production” (p. 40). Reasons for this trade-off are numerous and include both tangible and intangible factors. For example, a tangible factor could involve the firrn’s manufacturing equipment. The nature of the equipment may impose constraints on the ability to retool in response to a product innovation that has different manufacturing requirements than the previous product. Intangible factors include organizational and administrative design limitations, such as the failure to learn across fimctions and projects and/or the existence of cultural rigidities within the fum.l3 For example, Hayes et. a1. (1988) describe how the failure to align development “windows” properly between product and process innovations can undermine innovation (pp. 298-99), and they emphasize that strategic interactions ’3 See Hayes et.al (p. 338) for discussions relating to organizational firnctions. See Ginn (1995, pp. 357- 410) for a discussion relating organizational culture to technical creativity. 18 between the two dimensions are of primary importance to the success of any project.” Many of these factors could be characterized as side-affects stemming fi'om problems related to firm size, such as excessive bureaucracy, communication breakdowns, and labor issues.” In the economics literature, the idea of a trade-off is reflected in research that details empirical differences in the intensity and composition of R&D among firms. Acs and Audretsch (1987, 1991) provide evidence that not only does R&D intensity vary among firms in different industries, but among firms in the same industry according to firm size (and other factors). They find that many of the most important innovations are produced by relatively small, new firms, whereas large firms tend to focus on incremental innovations. This implies one or both of the following: (1) firm size provides incentives for larger firms to concentrate on incremental product innovation, or (2) firm size inhibits the ability to create drastic product innovations. Doyle (1994) provides evidence that the value of overall R&D varies with firm size in high technology industries. Of course, this suggests the question: does the efficiency/value of product R&D and process R&D vary with the size of the firm, and if so, how? Whether the interaction, if it exists, is positive, as Athey and Schmutzler suggest, or negative, as much of the management literature implies, could have important consequences for firm evolution. For example, the trade-off hypothesis provides a " For further evidence, see Gruber, 1981. There is also evidence that venture-type corporate programs are more successful and stable if they fit the overall strategy of the corporation (Gompers and Lerner, I998). The fact that non-strategic ventures are less successful is consistent with the idea that organizational factors are important to R&D. 19 plausible explanation for Cohen and Klepper’s (1996) finding that process innovation increases with firm size. Organizational constraints, be they tangible or intangible, prevent the firm from performing product R&D and process R&D with equal efficiency as the firm grows in size. If extemalities between product and process R&D exist, they will be influenced by observable internal and external firm and industry characteristics. These characteristics are closely linked to organizational factors within the firm and external appropriability incentives. “Forces both inside and outside the industrial firm influence the (innovation) process. Outside forces include users’ needs, changing prices of inputs, competitive stresses, and government stimuli and regulations. The inside forces include the firrn’s resource allocations; the product and process technologies themselves; the people, organization, and communication patterns involved in producing innovations, and the technical resources and strengths of the firm” (Utterback, 1979). In addition, a trade-off would likely be a result of a combination of both organizational design constraints and tangible factors. For example, organizational design constraints may imply that a fertile product-nmovating environment requires “a stimulating, supportive leadership and a positive, encouraging organizational climate that ‘5 For example, see Hayes and Wheelwright (1984), Utterback (1994). 20 allows employees to take risks” (Holt and Seetzen (1975), p. 226), whereas a fertile process-innovating environment requires a structured organization with a focus on cost containment and repetition. These goals may very well be mutually exclusive. Creating an environment conducive to one inhibits the ability to create an environment that fosters the other. Furthermore, the frrm could be faced with tangible constraints as well. For example, if the firm competes successfully in a market with a relatively fast innovation pace (3 short technological-life-cycle), it will be proficient, by definition, at product innovation. However, it will also have less time to develop production efficiencies (process irmovate) because the optimal production process may change over the course of the PLC. This will impose additional costs on manufacturing because of the constant need to retool and alter production processes to meet the demands of the new product. In this way, a product innovation may create an extemality on the process side by necessitating different production techniques and/or forcing the firm to retool. Pine et. a1. (1993) discuss innovation within the context of mass customization and the problems inherent in establishing an organizational design supportive of both dimensions. They relate a particularly illuminating story about the difficulties Toyota Motor Company encountered as it attempted, beginning in the late 1980’s, to transform itself fi'om a firm that focused on ‘continuous process improvement’ to one which was able to make “... varied and often individually customized products at the low cost of standardized, mass-produced goods” (p 108). Mass customization, in which a firm strives to add additional value to each good produced yet manufacture them at low cost, could be considered a product AND process-improving system. It attempts to increase 21 demand for the product using product enhancements while simultaneously keeping costs to a minimum through process enhancements. As Toyota came to realize, mass customization is an entirely different world than continuous process improvement (whereby a firm endeavors to manufacture goods at low costs - although with the co- requisite of preserving quality), which could be considered a one—dimensional process innovating system. The authors illustrate this point by noting that after some early success, Toyota was forced to retreat from its goal of becoming a mass-customizer. Part of the problem was the economic recession in the early 1990’s, but that wasn’t the whole story. Management was forced to acknowledge that “continuous improvement and mass customization require very different organizational designs, values, management roles and systems, learning methods, and ways of relating to customers” (p.109). Whereas process improvement requires a relentless pursuit of quality through a vision of “being the best” and managers constantly striving to tighten the links between processes, mass customization requires a “... dynamic network of relatively autonomous operating units” (p. 110). In attempting to evolve into a firm proficient in innovation in two dimensions, Toyota discovered that success in one dimension may not be compatible with success in the other. 22 C. Returns to Innovation 1. Determinants The following discussion is concerned exclusively with returns fiom private firms and does not consider the deterrninates or measures of value derived from innovation in the public domain, such as Universities or publicly funded research institutes. With that said, before a firm can undertakes an R&D project it “... must consider the cost of doing research, the probability of succeeding, and the likely degree of competition...” (Quinnbach, 1993). The cost of doing research is heavily influenced by the firrn’s level of commitment and its ability to manage costs, which in turn rests upon the efficiency of the firm’s organization - a consideration I already have discussed. The other two considerations, the probability of succeeding and the degree of competition, depend on three types of uncertainty: (1) technological uncertainty, (2) strategic uncertainty, and (3) market uncertainty. Technological uncertainty refers to the possibility that the firm may not possess the necessary technical expertise to develop an opportunity into a viable commercial innovation. Strategic uncertainty arises from the possibility that the firm may not be the first to introduce the innovation to the market. Market uncertainty results from a potential lack of demand from buyers.” An alternative but related way of looking at these considerations, sans costs, is within the conditional probability framework developed by Mansfield et. a1. (1977). 23 They use three success probabilities to characterize the success rate of innovations: (1) the probability that a technical goal will be achieved, (2) the probability that the resulting innovation, conditional on technical success, will be commercialized, and (3) the probability, conditional on successful commercialization, that the innovation will yield a profitable return. On average, 27% of the projects they studied ultimately were profitable. Mansfield’s first success probability corresponds closely to technological uncertainty. His third success probability can be seen to include strategic uncertainty and perhaps market uncertainty. Success probability 2 is less concrete. It could refer to market uncertainty in that the firm decides simply to shelve the product because there is no anticipation of demand. It also could refer to financial constraints, to a firm’s inability to adequately take advantage of its resources, or to all of the above. In any case, R&D costs and the rate of success of any of these probabilities most certainly will vary among firms and therefore will depend upon two considerations. First, the characteristics of the firm itself (its assets and organizational design), and second, the characteristics of the industry or industries in which it competes (market conditions). I have already discussed the impact of organizational constraints on innovation, so I will turn my attention to the importance of market conditions, or “outside forces” in Utterback's terminology, to determine the profitability of innovation. Market conditions provide the external incentives that drive the firm to innovate, and include technological '6 Adapted from Encaoua et. a1. (1996). 24 push, market pull, and appropriability.17 Technological push refers to the idea that there are exogenous technological innovation opportunities that firms can develop and commercialize profitably. Market (or demand) pull refers to the firrn’s perception of the potential demand for the innovation.18 Appropriability is the extent to which a firm can capture the new economic rents associated with a product or process innovation, and depends inversely on the extent to which the innovation is a public good. - In regard to the first two conditions, the essential point is that the firm’s ability to develop technical opportunities is squandered if it cannot identify which of those opportunities will have a market demand. The ability to both recognize and develop technical opportunities allows a firm to define a set of possible and “demanded” innovations (in the case of a process innovation, the demander can be thought of as the firm itself) which will lead to profitability. Calantone et. al. (1996) point out that although a firm’s R&D department responds primarily to technological push factors, without an effective interface with the demand-pull source of innovative ideas, technologically superior products can be developed that fill no need in the marketplace. Thus, an organizational failure can be the cause of a lower success probability 2. Profit from innovation ultimately is determined by appropriability conditions in the industry. Therefore, of those innovations that pass the first two criteria, the firm must reasonably be sure that the returns are proprietary and large enough to earn a profit. Demand for the product must translate into demand for the product produced by the firm. ‘7 Scherer and Ross (1990). '8 Holt and Seetzen ( 1975, p. 225) refer to this as “need pull”. 25 If other firms can quickly and cheaply offer a competitive product and compete the economic rents to zero, then the product likely will not pay for its development costs. The level of appropriability in large part is a function of the concentration in the industry, the essential idea behind Schumpeter’s Hypothesis. Appropriability also is influenced greatly by patent laws and regulation. See Scherer and Ross (1990) for a discussion of appropriability and patent protection. Quirmbach (1993) analyzes appropriability under a variety of industry conditions; he considers alternative market structures (Bertrand competition, Coumot competition, and collusion), patent protection or no patent protection, and projects with a high probability of success vs. projects with a low probability of success. He restricts his analysis to product innovation, primarily to cases where patent protection is unavailable and irrritation is not immediate. He points out that a higher technical success probability, assuming it is industry-wide, could adversely affect the industry’s level of appropriability and reduce incentives to perform R&D. This effect tends to increase as collusion decreases or the new technology exhibits increasing returns to scale. His results also suggest that the anticipation of post innovation collusion encourages R&D investment in the short run, but realized collusion later may discourage continued R&D investment if patent protection is available. Under his assumptions, patents also are more likely to increase appropriability in industries where new technologies exhibit increasing returns to production. Generally, appropriability is lower in Bertrand industries if the industry is not perfectly collusive (in fact, expected profits are zero if there is more than one firm). Appropriability is generally higher in Coumot 26 industries with the level varying depending on the project parameters. Although Quirmbach derives a wide range of results under a variety of conditions, he does not consider process innovation. This is an important omission because the level of appropriability can vary between product innovation and process innovation. There is little doubt that revenue incentives to innovate are strong in both dimensions. In addition, it is likely that these incentives are complementary. Recall that studies by Capon et. a1. (1992) and Landau and Rosenberg (1992) indicate that those firms who are able to perform well in both areas of innovation are usually the most competitive and profitable. Taking this idea a step further, Cohen and Klepper (1996) develop a model of product and process R&D based on such complementary incentives. They derive a positive relationship between ex ante output and process R&D intensity, as measured by the ratio of process R&D to the sum of process and product R&D. The returns to a product innovation are enhanced if the firm subsequently decreases its production costs via a process innovation. They state their basic relationship as follows: In =fq"! /(fq”1 + grhq + 10”?) [1.1] where p = the ratio of process R&D to total R&D. The numerator represents the profit maximizing level of process R&D as a fimction of ex ante output q. The second term in the denominator represents the profit maximizing level of product R&D as a function of q and as a function of K, the additional output derived from new product innovation. The parameters f and g represent industry level technological opportunities for process and product innovation, respectively. The parameters fli represent the marginal returns to innovation and can differ between product and process innovation. 27 The implication of equation 1.1 is that the derivative of p with respect to q is positive “.. as long as the marginal return to process R&D declines sufficiently slowly relative to product R&D” (p. 235). Their equation implies that a process innovation will reduce costs and increase the price-cost margin. Both of these factors will increase the returns to a given product innovation which itself increases the price-cost margin but now can be applied to a larger quantity, thanks to the ex-ante process innovation. Given an innovation in one dimension, any improvement in the other will allow an increase in the firm’s ability to appropriate the returns to the second. These revenue complementarities provide incentives to allocate R&D resources to both types of innovation, but not symmetrically. As the firm’s sales grow, the incentive to process innovate begins to surpass the incentive to product innovate, thus implying a positive relationship between firm size (sales) and the returns to process innovation intensity. Unfortunately, neither Quirmbach nor Cohen and Klepper consider organizational factors in the R&D allocation decision. Although it may be true that improvements in one area lead to more revenue as another area improves, this does not necessarily imply that improvements in one area will make improvements in the other area less costly. Not only are there the usual diminishing returns to R&D investment within a particular dimension, but the rate of dirnirrishment could be affected by the other dimension. 28 2. Measurement The value of innovative activity is determined by a variety of factors. Not surprisingly, measuring the value of innovative activity is a complex issue. Regardless of methodology, measuring the returns to innovation requires choosing an appropriate proxy for the innovative activity itself. There are two common candidates: research and development expenditures (R&D) and patents.19 Both are considered excellent, although not perfect, indicators of the level of innovativeness. Patents are theoretically appealing because they are considered a true output. Griliches (1990) has argued that patent statistics, which are very detailed, are a superior indicator of innovative ability. However, many innovations are not patented. For example, Cordes, et. al. (1987) find that many high technology firms do not patent their innovations because of the short technological-life—cycles in their industries.20 R&D, on the other hand, is a better indicator of the effort put forth by the innovator. However, R&D expenditures do not necessarily translate into successful innovations, and R&D spending may not be the only source of innovation. Moreover, R&D expenditure data “are subject to considerable error in reporting; firms are given considerable latitude in classifying activities used for financial reporting” (Doyle, ‘9 Not surprisingly, large corporations are responsible for the majority of both. In 1988, for instance, 73% of the patents granted to US inventors were to corporations (82% of foreign patents were to corporations), with 25% going to individual inventors (Griliches, 1990). 2° See Griliches (1990) and Hall (1998) for a summary of the advantages and disadvantages of each. 29 1994).21 Thus, determining the micro or macro impact of R&D spending on innovation is empirically difficult. However, the situation appears to be improving. In the US, Standard and Poor’s Compustat data compiles extensive R&D information primarily from 10-K reports to the Securities and Exchange Commission. The National Science Foundation conducts annual R&D surveys, and surveys by others are conducted periodically.22 Beginning in 1989, the UK. began requiring firms to report R&D expenditures as a standard accounting practice. In summary, the choice between using patents, R&D spending, or some other metric as a proxy for innovation boils down to methodology and data availability. Another common issue involves the choice of an appropriate measure for the returns to innovation. Several measures have been used, including profitability itself, profit margin (rate of return), total factor productivity, and market value. For example, a stock market event study measures the change in the market value of a stock before and after a specified event has occurred. The problem is determining the appropriate points in time for the each measurement. This approach often is used to study the impact of patents, although it is important to choose the patent(s) carefirlly (Austin, 1993). Many patents are redundant because often there are “many viable solutions to a technical problem, and other firms can ‘invent around’ a given patented solution” (Scherer and 2' Mansfield (1986) and Hulten and Robertson (1984) both find that the introduction of the R&D tax credit in 1981 resulted in a considerable amount of non-R&D related spending being reclassified as R&D investment to take advantage of the credit. 22 Examples include the Industrial Research Institutes R&D survey annually conducted by the Center for Innovation Management Studies (which I use in this study), the survey conducted by Levin, Bohen, and Mowery, 1985, and the European Innovation Monitoring System (EIMS). 30 Ross (1990) p. 624), and many patents are simply not commercially viable. It is known that the distribution of the value of patents is extremely skewed, and thus many patents contribute little to economic growth. Other methodologies include creating a metric for innovation success and regressing it against profits (McGrath and Romeri, 1994), or regressing various firm and industry characteristics against the firm’s rate of return. Geroski et. al. (1993) use this latter approach to estimate the impact of innovation on the profit margin of a large sample of UK firms. Using the number of significant innovations produced by a firm as their measure of innovativeness, they found that an additional innovation contributed anywhere between 6.1% and 16.5% to a firm’s profit margin. The most common approach to measuring the returns to innovation involves relating total factor productivity to some measure(s) of innovation data (R&D often is the more natural choice because of its input nature). For instance, another study by Geroski (1989) examined the effect of innovation and other characteristics on total factor productivity growth using a sample of 79 industries in the United Kingdom spanning a three-year period. He found that innovation was by far the most important factor in the study, accounting for as much as 70% of observed productivity growth. He also found evidence that the impact of a single innovation is more durable over time than the impact of other factors, such as entry by domestic or foreign firms. Despite the important results from this methodology, this approach and others like it may be difficult to implement for several reasons: first, long lags often exist between R&D spending and the realization of the returns fiom R&D. The lag introduces uncertainty in the appropriate specification of 31 the model, and disqualifies many sources of data that are not long enough to cover the appropriate time span. Second, a significant lag time between action and the observation of results limits the firm or policy maker’s use of the relationship as a tool for planning. Third, the measurement of innovative activities at the firm or industry level can be difficult to match with other inputs, partly as a result of these same lags, and partly because of data limitations. Therefore, it can be difficult to incorporate other inputs, such as other costs, into the analysis (Hall, 1998). One popular alternative to measuring the returns to innovation, used in this study, is a stock market valuation approach using R&D expenditure data. This approach has gained popularity since it was first introduced by Griliches (1981). The market valuation approach regresses R&D expenditures, other intangible assets, and tangible assets against the market value of the firm. The advantage to this method is that it avoids the problems presented by the lag between R&D and its returns. This method is not a panacea, however, because it is limited to evaluating private firms that are traded on a well functioning financial market, and therefore it does not evaluate the public returns to innovative activity. In addition, it limits the researcher’s ability to incorporate line of business data into the study. Nevertheless, it is particularly well suited to measuring the value of intangible assets because it incorporates these assets directly into the valuation equation, thereby leveraging the idea that publicly traded corporations are bundles of assets (such as knowledge, reputation, and tangible assets). The market valuation approach is basically a variation of the hedonic regression method, which attempts to “determine the marginal value of a particular intangible asset 32 by regressing the market price for firms that possess the asset on various characteristics of the firms” (Hall (1998), p. 4). In the market valuation of R&D application, one measures the marginal value of an additional dollar of investment in a given type of corporate asset, namely R&D. A central issue with this methodology is the method of valuing the firm. The method most often employed follows traditional finance literature. The market value of the firm is determined by the present discounted value, or net present value, of its expected cash flow into the future. V = NPV(discounted cash flow) . [1.2] In the finance literature, cash flow to the common stock owner usually is represented by current and future expected dividends. In turn, the dividends paid out by the firm will be a direct function of its earnings, or income stream. V13, = NP V(income stream (dividends)) . [1.2’] A more explicit representation of Equation 1.2’ is the following: V1,, = Incomet +Incomet+ 1 /(1 +k)+1ncomet+2 /(I +k)2 + + Incomet+n /(1 +k)” [1.2”] where k is the required rate of return on the common stock. For a depreciable asset, n will equal the number of periods before the asset’s value is fully depreciated. All things 33 equal, higher depreciation rates will imply smaller n, reduce the number of terms in the net present value computation, and therefore lower market values. Likewise, higher required rates of return also will lower market value.23 Finally, in considering the market value effects of firm assets, it is necessary to control for the expected level of investor risk. Risk comes in two varieties, systematic and unsystematic. Unsystematic risk refers to risk unique to the firm, such as management capabilities, R&D uncertainty, competition, or regulation. Systematic risk refers to risk the variability of a stock’s return attributable to factor’s affecting the market as a whole, such as interest rate changes, inflation, and consumer confidence. Theoretically, all unsystematic risk can be eliminated through diversification, and thus the reward to bearing risk should depend solely on its systematic risk (Ross et. all. (1995) p. 347). Therefore, the value of an asset depends on its expected cash flow discounted appropriately, where systematic risk is a necessary factor in the discounting process, and influences the investor’s required rate of return. In fact, following Doyle (1994, p. 59) the required rate of return, k*, for a firm can be represented as k‘ = rf+ flf(km — rf) [1.3] where rf is the risk free rate (e.g. treasury security yield), km is the market’s expected 2’ Given some simplifying assumption regarding income (or dividend) growth over time, two special cases of equation 1.2” can be determined. First, if a zero growth rate is assumed, equation 2.1 ” simplifies to Vi, t = Income /k. Second, assuming a constant growth rate in income, equation 2.1” sirrrplifies to 34 return on the overall market portfolio, and ,8] is the firrn’s beta. The beta is a traditional financial measure of risk relating the volatility of an individual common stock to the volatility of a broad market index, such as the Standard and Poor’s 500, the DOW, or the NASDAQ. Higher volatility relative to the index implies higher risk, but also larger returns.24 Instead of the interest rate, k. is used as the discount rate in equation 1.2” to obtain the net present value of the firm’s cash flow/income, and hence its market valuation. Thus, the higher the perceived risk by investors, the higher the beta, the higher the required rate of return, and the lower the firrn’s market valuation. In order to apply the above analysis toward the goal of measuring the retums to innovation, the typical model of market value hypothesizes that the discounted value of current and future income, and hence the value of the firm, is a function of its n number of assets: V“ =fi(Income stream, (A ,1, A1,, ...... A n, t )), [1.4] or more simply, Vi', =ft(A,.,, A1,, ...... Any) [1.4’] V13, = lncome(l +g) /(k-g), where g is the growth rate. 2‘ In some cases, rather than the beta, the Standard & Poor’s ranking of earnings and dividend stability is used (Hirschey, 1982). 35 In the case of constant returns to scale of the profit function and a single asset, we obtain the familiar result that the market value of the firm is a product of the book value of its assets times a ‘shadow price’, commonly referred to as Tobin’s q. V, = q,g(A,, A2, ......) . [1.5] Several assumptions underlie this method: first, it is assumed that firms invest in these assets in a value-maximizing manner. Second, appealing to the efficient markets hypothesis, it is assumed that the financial market on which the firm trades is efficient, and that all optimal asset trades have occurred. Finally, although the true functional form of the function f (or g) is unknown, it is assumed that a satisfactory approximation exists. Typically, and primarily for econometric considerations, these approximations assume a linear or a traditional Cobb-Douglas form. The assets within the function f generally are classified as tangible or intangible. Tangible capital usually is represented by the book value of the firm at time t, and intangible capital reflects the stock of knowledge capital and advertising capital at time t. Advertising capital, typically represented by the sum of the weighted flow of advertising expenditures over the previous x number of years (typically 5 years), reflects the value imputed fi'om the product’s reputation. Likewise, the flow of R&D expenditures over the previous x number of years is used to represent knowledge capital. The method of weighting previous expenditures varies from study to study. Occasionally, current profits or cash flow is included in the valuation equation to account for market power or long- 36 run profitability not related to advertising or R&D (Hall, 1993 and Hirschey, 1982). Also occasionally, the grth rate of sales is included as a proxy for expected future growth of the firm, which some view as an important factor in common stock valuation (Hall, 1993) Given the above, several specifications for estimating market valuation are possible. After taking the natural logarithm of both Sides and applying approximations, the linear model and the Cobb-Douglas model as specified by Hall (1998) are Log VIJ =10g qr + at Log Air + 7: Ki,/Ai,! ’ [1-6] and Log Vt, =10g q, + 0? Log Ar, + 6!. Log (Kr/Au). [1-7] respectively, where V“ represents the market value of the firm at time t, q, is Tobin’s q, which in the regression represents the intercept term, A i, , represents tangible assets, and Kt: represents intangible assets. The last term in each specification is expanded additively to include each type of intangible asset: advertising, R&D, risk, and any other included terms. Alternatively, some researchers, notably Hirschey (1982) and Doyle (1994) specified valuation equations without the log transform. Like Hall, Hirschey used the ratio of intangible assets to tangible assets as independent variables, while Doyle refrained from using ratios, instead preferring to apply a Taylor expansion to equation 37 1.5. One advantage to Doyle’s methodology is that it more easily lends itself to working with first-differenced equations. If the time period over which the data extends is of short duration, as is often the case, it may be difficult to construct a reliable measure of the stock of intangible capital, and transforming the data through first-differencing allows the researcher to work with flow variables instead of stock variables. FurthermOre, first- differencing allows more flexibility in the treatment of risk. According to Hall (1998), researchers using United States data on manufacturing firms typically find that each dollar invested in R&D leads to an additional market capitalization of between $2.5 and $8, with the stock of R&D valued between 0.5 to 2 times the value of ordinary assets. Despite expectations to the contrary, the addition of industry specific dummies does not change the estimates on average. Another interesting result is that the shadow value of R&D is not stable over time, and is sensitive to the period examined. For example, the late sixties and seventies was a period of high valuation of R&D, while the late eighties and nineties was a period of low valuation. Hall offers two explanations for this: first, variations in the value of ordinary assets caused the value of intangible assets to vary in an inverse manner. Second, beginning in the 1980’s, declines in the value of R&D assets occurred in high-tech industries where the returns to R&D are short-lived. Another possibility, which Hall does not consider, is that financial markets value some types of R&D more than other types. Thus, changes in the composition of R&D over time will change the valuation of intangible assets as a whole. 38 II. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND MODEL Geroski (1995) stated that “entry appears to be relatively easy, but survival is not” (p. 435). Clearly, the firrn’s ability to adapt to changing market conditions will determine whether it survives. In my view, an essential component of this process of adaptation is the efficient allocation of R&D resources between the product dimension and the process dimension within the constraints of the organization. Organizational design is an essential ingredient for analyzing innovation. In the theory that follows, the purpose of defining organization-related concepts is not necessarily to build a model using each concept, but to provide a reasonable explanation for observed R&D allocation strategies and the value placed on them by financial markets. This section develops a theoretical model that describes the firm’s allocation of innovative resources between product R&D and process R&D. I show that investment in organizational design is not necessarily without hidden costs or benefits; organizational strategies in one dimension could interact with strategies in the other to create extemalities from one dimension to the other. I first discuss and develop a general framework of the model and define important concepts. Then I develop a corresponding mathematical theory from which I derive some specific hypotheses. 39 A. Interactions Between Product and Process Innovation Recall that Acs and Audretsch (1987) and Cohen and Klepper (1996) discuss the idea that the returns to process innovation are greater relative to product innovation as the level of firm output increases. I refer to this as the appropriability efl‘ect. Specifically, the appropriability effect states that a given process innovation will generate more net revenue than a given product innovation as output increases (when this occurs, I refer to the appropriability effect as positive -- if the reverse is true, I refer to the effect as negative). Thus, there are apprOpriability incentives to focus innovative efforts on process R&D as output increases. However, incentives do not always translate to behavior. Internal factors necessary for the firm to capitalize on the appropriability effect influence firm allocation strategies, but have not been explored in previous research. For example, a product innovation may require different manufacturing techniques than the firm currently uses, and impose adjustment costs on the process side. In addition, organizational factors likely will influence the effectiveness of innovative efforts in and across dimensions. For these reasons, the existence of the appropriability effect may not provide enough incentive for the firm to allocate R&D resources in accordance with it. In the model that follows, the basic input that determines the firm’s ability to produce commercial innovations, in addition to direct R&D expenditures, is organizational design. I define organizational design as a collection of organizational design practices (ODP’s). An ODP refers to a part of the organization with a distinct 40 form of its own and which has a specific firnction or purpose within the firm. It could be a training program, a specific management structure, an R&D center, a ‘total quality management’ strategy, a team, an operational learning and control system, etc. Organizational design practices are mechanisms for establishing firm specific capabilities, particularly as they relate to the two innovative dimensions within the firm -- product and process. A well functioning, well-managed organization comprises a collection of ODP’S in each dimension, and is highly flexible.25 Anderson and Schmittlein (1984) and Milgrom and Roberts (1990) describe a tendency for ODPs to be “cluster ” in firms, thereby providing evidence that many ODP’s are complementary.“ This is consistent with Athey and Stem’s hypothesis that product innovation and process innovation are complementary. Another plausible hypothesis for clustering may be that some ODP’s are more suited for product innovation than process, and vice versa. Those firms with a strategic orientation towards process (product) innovation would naturally tend to have a collection of ODP’s more suited to process (product) innovation. It is also possible that ODP’S afford a pathway through which one dimension can interact with the other. This could happen if those ODP’s more suited to one dimension are functionally incompatible, or functionally complementary, with ODP’s more suited to the other dimension. For an example of ODP incompatibility, suppose the firm has a product innovation ODP comprised of teams organized around specific product lines. A ‘5 By flexible I refer to how easily ODPs change and respond to outside stimuli. See footnote 4 for definitions of flexibility. 41 prod on are existi CIITB‘. had. flexib subsequent adoption of a process oriented ODP, such as an operational control system, may interfere with the creative flow of the design teams and limit their effectiveness. Therefore, to the degree that these ODPs interfere with each other, the efficiency of the overall organization will be impaired, and the firm will exhibit trade-offs between product and process innovation. In contrast, complementary ODP’s would have the opposite effect; they would provide incentives to invest in both dimensions and enhance the effectiveness of the overall organization. The existence of an interaction may also affect the firm’s ability to respond to external conditions. The more likely it is that potential ODP’s are incompatible with existing ODP’s, the more limitations placed on the firrn’s ability to change or augment its current OD as market conditions dictate, thereby impairing its flexibility. On the other hand, if ODP’s are overall complementary, then the firm should have a higher degree of flexibility, all else equal. If incompatibilities exist, the firm conceivably could choose to invest primarily in a single dimension. An exclusive collection of ODP’s in one particular dimension may allow the firm to reap the benefits of their within-dimension complementarities while avoiding any negative organizational extemalities. This will provide it a more efficient, albeit one—dimensional, organization while retaining a high degree of flexibility in that dimension. Of course, there may be adverse revenue consequences down the road. However, a firm may augment its internal R&D with external R&D, thus avoiding negative interactions while maintaining a profitable two-dimensional structure. In 26 Athey and Stern (1998) develop a method to test for these relationships. 42 contrast, complementary ODP’s would have the opposite effect; they would provide incentives to invest in both dimensions and eventually lead to positive revenue consequences, and provide more flexibility for R&D allocation. The point is that product innovation and process innovation are not conducted independent of each other. It is quite possible that interactions between them, via organizational considerations or some other mechanism, produce either trade-offs or complementarities between dimensions and affect the optimal allocations of product and process R&D. In smnmary, it is clear that the appropriability effect will tend to create incentives for higher process R&D activity relative to product R&D activity as the size of the firm increases. However, it also is possible that organizational requirements for successful product innovation may interact with the organizational requirements for successful process innovation in one of two ways: in a complimentary fashion that enhances innovation in each dimension, or as a trade-off that reduces innovation efficiency in each dimension. The implication is that a large enough interaction between product and process innovation, either positive or negative, may interfere with the appropriability effect. For example, a trade-off between product and process innovation could induce the firm to become one-dimensional; that is, abandon innovation in one dimension altogether and focus solely on the other, and look to increase external R&D. Alternatively, an asymmetric spillover from one dimension to the other may significantly change the optimal allocation strategy from one that supports the appropriability effect to one that supports a negative appropriability effect. The following model, which builds upon 43 Cohen and Klepper (1996), incorporates appropriability incentives and interactions between product and process innovation into a formal structure. B. The Model The model that follows is based on Cohen and Klepper’s (1996) product and process R&D incentive model. I extend their model to incorporate interactions between product and process innovation while retaining their basic revenue incentive framework. The goal of the R&D decision-maker is to maximize profit generated from innovative output in each innovation dimension i, product and process.27 Suppose at time t the firm introduces a new product variant. The product variant will increase the price buyers are willing to pay for the product, and thus increase the price-cost margin on each unit of output produced. The introduction of a process innovation also will increase the price-cost margin, but through a decrease in the average cost per unit of output. The total revenue generated from either type of innovation will be a direct function of the price- cost margin times the level of ex-ante output. Following Cohen and Klepper, let qt denote ex-ante output, measured as the number of units of output sold. In the product innovation dimension, let ht denote the fraction of the firrn’s existing buyers that purchase the finn’s new product variant, Z, the units of output produced (and sold) of the new product variant that results from product innovation, and A D,t the time until the market imitates the product innovation (the parameter A 1),, reflects the level of competition in the industry). Therefore, the total net revenue generated from product R&D expenditures in time t can be represented as Vt(Dt) = AD,t(htqt + 29 Ut(Dt) , ' [2.11 where Ut(Dt) represents the price cost margin attained from product R&D expenditures (D1). The price cost margin is an absolute measure of the increase in the price attained from the product enhancement. It is the difference, attributed to product R&D, between the price of the new variant and the price of the old variant. In an industry that was perfectly competitive prior to product innovation (price equals marginal cost), U(D,) would be equal to the post-innovation price minus average/marginal cost.28 To reflect the idea that more product R&D expenditures increases the price cost margin but at a declining rate, I assume U '(D) > 0 and U ”(D) < 0. In the process dimension, h=1 and 2:0, and thus the revenue generated from process R&D expenditures can be denoted, ’7 In the model that follows, I will abstract from any moral hazard that would provide incentives for the decision-maker to invest in R&D in a non profit maximizing manner. 2’ I could have defined 2 as a function of ex ante output, q. However, Z is defined as the number of new customers attracted to the enhanced product that did not previously buy the obsolete version. Although there may be a relationship, I do not see it as a direct, first order relationship, but as an indirect influence (neither do Cohen and Klepper). Therefore, the parameter b reflects an indirect relationship, and there is no need to define Z as a function of q. Furthermore, this specification does not detract from the basic intuition of the model nor affect the directional irrrpact of the results of the analysis below, but it would complicate the analysis. 45 Vt(Rd = AR,rqut(Rd [22] where R, represents process R&D expenditures. Analogous to product R&D, I assume U ’(R) > O and U "(R) < 0. Also analogous to product R&D, A R,t represents the time until the cost advantage is matched by the industry. Given 2.1 and 2.2, total firm net revenue generated from R&D activities at time t, 17;, can be represented as, 17t = AD,t(htqt + Zr) Ut(Dr) + AR,ttht(Rt) - Dr - Rt. [23] This is the basic revenue-incentive framework used by Cohen and Klepper.29 It implies revenue incentives are greater for process R&D than product R&D as firm ex ante sales increase. However, rather than specify an explicit functional form for U(*), they specify a general form for its derivatives: U ’(R) = mRR—I/fi and U ’(D) = mDD‘I/fl, where ,6 defines the rate at which the marginal return to process R&D and product R&D decline. In other words, the efficiency with which R&D is performed is a direct function of the value of ,6. The parameters mR and mu represent industry level technological opportunities for process and product R&D. They chose this specification for the following reasons: “it is convenient because it allows ‘R’ and ‘D’ to be solved for explicitly as a function of q. This makes it possible to characterize the conditions that 46 need to h prim. Irvin III R&D. vi Sllllt I'll? need to hold to obtain the simple intuition suggested above as well as to derive detailed predictions that allow further testing of the model” (p. 234). Although they allow ,6 to vary in theory, they impose the restriction that ,6 is equal for product R&D and process R&D, which implies “the marginal returns to process and product R&D decline at the same rate as a function of the level of process and product spending” (p. 235). In many respects, Cohen and Klepper’s specification of U(*) is extremely powerful in its simplicity, but it is still somewhat limited for my purposes for several reasons. First, they do not consider a possible interaction between product and process innovation. Second, their assumption that ,6 is equivalent in each dimension is somewhat suspect. It amounts to the assumption that each dimension conducts innovative activity with equal efficiency. However, as the previous section demonstrated, this efficiency is dependent upon the organizational design of the firm. Therefore, to the extent that organization design is asymmetric between dimensions, this assumption is unwarranted. To extend Cohen and Klepper’s framework to incorporate the organizational design aspects of innovation, I alter their original specification by defining the price cost margin attained fi'om product R&D as U(D) = mDDaU +1) , [2.4] 2” All variables represent current period and thus the subscript t can be dropped from now on with no confusion. 47 whit prod deter assun proce- u y where m D represents the level of technological opportunities in the industry in the product dimension. The parameter or is analogous to Cohen and Klepper’s ,B(D); it determines the efficiency with which the firm employs its product R&D expenditures. I assume 0 f m D f 1 and 0 f a f 1. The parameter 2 represents a spillover effect fi‘om process innovation. This parameter lies between negative 1 and one; -1 < 2 < 1. Likewise, the price-cost margin function for process R&D can be defined as U(R) = mRR‘SU +9) [2.5] where OSmR,6§1and0_<_ 651. The discussion in the previous section suggests the parameters or and 8 are functions of organizational design. If 0]) represent the level of organizational design in the product dimension, then a = (#00). Extending this idea further, assume the efficiency of product R&D increases as the level of organizational design increases, but at a decreasing rate, i.e., a’>0 and a”<0. Likewise, for the process dimension, 6 = 6 (0R) and6’>0 and6"<0. Finally, the parameters 2 and 6 represent the interactions between product and process innovation and also are dependent upon organizational design; 2:2(0R) and 9=9(OD). Thus, if organizational design increases or decreases in one dimension, there are spillovers into the next dimension through these interaction terms. To reflect the idea 48 that the effect of the spillover into one dimension increases as the level of organizational design in the other dimension increases, but at a decreasing rate, and that the increase is in the same direction as the initial sign of the term, I assume |2’ >0, l2 ”|<0 and |6’|>0, |6’ ’|<0. In addition, assume the interaction is equally dependent on irmovation efficiency for each dimension; i.e., 0R = 01) implies 2 = 6 and 2’ = 6’. The purpose of the interaction terms is to capture the basic intuition behind the organizational design aspects of irmovation outlined in the previous section, and this assumption in no way detracts fiom this basic intuition. I also make the simplifying assumption that the signs of 2 and 6 are the same. Therefore, 2,6 > 0 implies complementarities between product and process innovation, 2,6 < 0 implies a trade-off, and 2,6 = 0 implies there is no interaction.” This specification is convenient because it defines an explicit firnctional form for U(*) while retaining the useful properties of Cohen and Klepper’s original specification — i.e., it allows D and R to be solved for explicitly as functions of q and the exogenous parameters by solving the first order conditions for D and R. It also characterizes the impact of organizational design on the effectiveness of R&D expenditures in a manner ’° Fixing the signs of 2 and 6to be the same amounts to the assumption that there is roughly an equivalent spillover effect on each dimension. For most firms, I see no reason for this assumption not to hold. Furthermore, this assumption does not detract from the basic intuition of the model nor affect the directional impacts of the interactions in the analysis below, but it would complicate the analysis. 49 T1 or consistent with the intuition outlined in the previous section.31 Equations 2.4 and 2.5 imply that equation 2.3 now can be written as: 17=AD (hq+Z)mDD“(1+") +AquRR5(1+9—D—R. [2.3’] The relationships between profit, revenue, cost, and each type of R&D are depicted in Figures 1 and 2. It is clear that the optimal (profit maximizing) levels of R&D occur where the slope of the revenue curves equal 1, the slope of the total cost curve. The position of the revenue curve depends on the exogenous parameters in the model. If A Dm D > A Rm R then industry effects favor product innovation over process innovation, and total revenue from product innovation will be greater than that from process innovation, all else equal. Likewise, the firm specific efficiency and interaction parameters may favor one dimension over another. In addition, within the same industry, firm specific parameters will determine relative positions of revenue curves. The model allows for the profit maximizing level of R&D to differ for each type of R&D, and for total profit fi'om each type of R&D to differ. 3' In the analysis that follows, the parameters a, A, 5, and 9 are assumed exogenous to the current period allocation decision. This assumption may not be realistic in that it removes the ability of the firm to confiol the interaction. However, it is doubtful that organizational changes occur quickly. Athey and Stern (1998) consider such organizational changes as long-run decisions. Therefore, in a static framework like we have here, treating these parameters as exogenous is appropriate. While a static framework limits the power of the model, it sinrplifies the analysis dramatically, and still allows meaningful results to be derived. A more comprehensive analysis would endogenize these parameters within the framework of a dynamic model. I leave this task to future researchers. 50 Revenue (5), Total Cost (8) A ‘ v-‘ v . ' ” ' p ” fl ,,,,,,,, V(Dz) / ''''' [a(I+4)<5(1+9)] ’ TC (slope=1 ) V(R) ——————————————— V(DI) [a(1+2)<6(1+6)] ’ Process R&D (SR), Product R&D (8D) Figure 1. Relationship between revenue, cost, and R&D expenditures. 51 Profi' Profit (SH) A b----——- -----—--—-— L.— --—-----———— h---‘---- —> D*, R* D*2 Pr ess R&D (SR), Prod ct R&D (8D) 11(1):) H(R) 11(1):) Figure 2. Relationship between R&D profit and R&D expenditures. 52 An important feature of the model is the dependency between process and product innovation through the interaction terms. By definition, if organizational design is enhanced in one dimension, it increases the efficiency of R&D in that dimension, but it also has an impact on the efficiency of R&D in the other dimension. This implies the following hypothesis: Hypothesis 1: The efliciency of product (process) R&D influences the efliciency (and revenue) of process (product) R&D according to the Sign of the interaction terms. To derive further predictions from the model, I first need to derive the profit maximizing levels of product R&D and process R&D. This is determined by setting marginal revenue equal to marginal cost for each type of R&D and solving for D and R. The first-order conditions for equation 2.3’ with respect to R&D expenditures are: £11 =17D = a(1+2) m1) A D (hq + Z)D“(1+")-1 _ 1, [2.6] d) and a: =IIR = 5(1+9)mR AR qR5(1+9)-1 — 1, [2.7] on To prevent the marginal revenue schedules from increasing, I impose the restrictions that 6(1 +6) <1 and a(1+2)<1. This ensures downward sloping marginal revenue curves. 53 Graphical representations of the marginal cost curve and alternative marginal revenue curves are depicted in Figure 3. As the graph shows, higher firm specific parameters in one dimension imply higher profit maximizing levels of R&D in that dimension. Thus, higher optimal spending on product R&D (D*2) versus process R&D imply exogenous parameters favoring product innovation. Conversely, unfavorable parameters for product innovation lead to a lower optimal product R&D allocation (D*,). In other words, for an equivalent amount of R&D, marginal revenue can be different for different types of R&D. The actual curves will vary from firm to firm based on the values of the exogenous industry and firm specific parameters in the model. Figure 3 demonstrates that if the parameters favor one dimension over the other, the optimal (profit maximizing) level of R&D will be higher in that dimension. Setting equations 2.6 and 2.7 equal to zero amounts to setting marginal revenue equal to l (marginal cost). Doing so and solving for D and R yields the net revenue maximizing levels of product and process R&D: 19* = [a(1 +2)A 1)»:qu + 2)] 1/(1-a(1+t)) , [2.8] and 12* = [6(1+6)ARqu] 1/(1-5(1+9)) . [2.9] 54 MR,MC Figure 3. Relationship between marginal revenue and marginal cost. 55 Using this specification, I can determine if and under what conditions the appropriability effect is positive. Recall, the appropriability effects states that the appropriability of process innovations increases relative to product innovations as firm sales increase. That is, larger firms can generate proportionately more net revenue from process innovation than product innovation. This implies that net revenue from process R&D should be an increasing fimction of sales. It also implies that the magnitude of the effect of sales on net revenue generated from process R&D should be greater than the effect of sales on net revenue generated from product R&D. Formally, 50743] - 1749]] > 0. [2.10] 361 Equation 2.3’ implies: 17(R) - 11(D) = M}; AR qR 56W - mD AD(hq + Z)D“(1+") . [2.11] Taking the derivative of this expression with respect to ex ante output q yields, 5mm] — 17(1)]; = mR AR R 5(1+9) - mD AD h D‘WT"). [2.12] é’q The case in which we are most interested is the sign of this expression at the optimal levels of product and process R&D. Inserting R* and D*, the net revenue-maximizing 56 values for process and product R&D, respectively, into expression 2.12 and simplifying yields, 6(17LR*2-17(D*)) = ARmR[5(1+6)ARqu]6(1+9)/(1-5(1+9)) [2.12’] é’q - hADmD[a(1+/1)Apmp(hq+22 ]“(1+")/(1"‘(1+’W Other than the dimension specific parameters, the primary difference between each term in this expression is the inclusion of h in the second (product R&D) term. Since h is always less than one, this expression will tend to be positive, supporting the appropriability effect. Therefore, the more successful the product innovation at retaining existing customers and attracting new ones, the less likely the appropriability effect will hold. Under the assumptions that all parameters in each dimension are held equal, with the exception of h and Z, the net revenue curves with respect to ex ante sales for each type of R&D are depicted in Figure 4.32 As the figure demonstrates, the difference in the slopes is determined by h, the proportion of existing accounts retained after product innovation. The intercept (I) for marginal revenue of product R&D occurs at mDADZD“(1 +1). The appropriability effect is supported in the region to the right of the intersection of the two curves. Notice however, if h=1, the curves never cross and the appropriability effect is never positive. ’2 There are two exceptions to this conclusion: first, if the exogenous parameters unduly favor the product dimension, and second, if hq+Z is significantly larger than q. Either of these situations could make the second term in equation 2.12’ greater than the first. I exarrrine these situations in more detail below. 57 H(R) 9 11(1)) A / fun): (h=1) / / TI(R) (D): (0 q Figure 6. Optimal allocation strategy with respect to sales. 61 After taking the derivative of this expression with respect to q, one derives the following condition that must hold for the derivative of expression 2.13 to be positive. (1 + Z/hq) > (1- 6(1+6))/(1-a(1+2)) . [2.14] (The proof is provided in appendix A). When this condition holds, firms allocate resources in accordance with a positive appropriability effect. Expression 2.14 has several interesting implications with regard to the optimal allocation strategy. To simplify things for the analysis below, assume the interaction terms are equal; i.e., 6 = 2. This assumption means that the spillovers fi'om one dimension to another are symmetrical. This has an implicit assumption that organizational design levels in each dimension are roughly equivalent. Although this may be a strong assumption, it allows me to isolate the impact of first-order changes in the other parameters, and still allows for meaningful analysis of interactions in general. In expression 2.14, notice that the sign does not depend on industry level parameters Ai and mi. This implies that industry effects are not critical in determining the optimal allocation strategy with respect to firm size. In addition, unless Z=0, the left- hand-side of the equation is always greater than one. Therefore, this expression will always hold if 6(1+6) 3 a(1 +2). Since we’re assuming the interaction effects are roughly equivalent, this implies positive appropriability effects when the process R&D efficiency parameter is greater than or equal to the product R&D efficiency parameter (in this case the marginal return schedule for process R&D will be larger and less steep than 62 the schedule for product R&D). Although this is a sufficient condition, it is not a necessary condition. Even an efficiency parameter for product R&D greater than that of process R&D does not preclude a positive appropriability effect. Therefore, I expect the appropriability effect should be positive in general. Hypothesis 2: As firm size increases, the marginal returns to process R&D will be larger than the marginal returns to product R&D at the optimal allocation. It is clear that the appropriability effect will be zero or negative if and only if 5(1 + 6) 3 a(1 +2). What is the minimum level of a for which the appropriability effect remains positive? Rearranging equation 2.14 yields: a(1+2) < 1-@q{1-6{1+6)l. [2.14’] [M + Z] If this condition does not hold, then the appropriability effect is not positive. First, note that as Z increases, this condition is more likely to hold. Therefore, the more new customers obtained by the product innovation, the more likely the appropriability effect Will be positive. Next, examine the term hq+Z. This term represents the number of CUStol'ners retained after the product innovation, plus the number of new customers acquired via the product innovation. Therefore, it represents total demand in the current period. If I let g represent the growth rate of sales in the current period, then hq+Z s 63 (1+g)q. That is, demand in the current period will equal demand in the previous period times the growth rate. Solving for Z and inserting the result into equation 2.14’ yields a< 1+g+h(6(1+Q-1). [2.14”] (1 +2) (1 +g) This expression states that the likelihood that the appropriability effect is positive or negative can be determined by examining the following factors: the efficiency parameters of product and process R&D, the interaction terms, the proportion of existing customers retained, and the growth rate of sales. Any change in the parameters on the right-hand-side of condition 2.14” that increases the RHS will support a positive appropriability effect, whereas any change to a parameter that decreases the RHS will support a negative appropriability effect. It can be shown that as the efficiency parameter of process R&D ((2 increases, the RHS increases (as one would expect). In contrast, as the proportion of existing customers retained (h) increases, the RHS declines, which does not support a positive appropriability effect (as we concluded from equation 2.12’). In addition, higher growth rates for sales (g) implies a smaller RHS. If 6 ¢ 2, then larger spillovers onto process R&D will increase the RHS whereas larger spillovers onto product R&D will decrease the RHS. However, the effects of the interaction terms are somewhat more complicated when we assume 6=2, or the somewhat weaker assumption that the interaction terms move concurrently. It can be shown, under the assumption that the interaction terms move concurrently, that the condition h<(l+g) ensures the RHS will increase as the interaction terms increase. This 64 condition should always hold. The above analysis implies the following propositions: Proposition 1 : A positive appropriability effect is less likely to exist when the firm retains a high proportion of its ex ante sales. Proposition 2: A positive appropriability eflect is less likely to exist in the presence of high sales growth. Proposition 3 : A positive appropriability effect is more likely to exist in the presence of trade-oflfs than in the presence of complementarities between product and process R&D. 65 C. Summation of Hypotheses/Propositions Hypothesis 1 : The efi‘iciency of product @rocess) R&D influences the efi‘iciency (and revenue) of process @roduct) R&D according to the sign of the interaction terms. Hypothesis 2: As firm size increases, the returns to process R&D will increase relative to the returns to product R&D. Proposition 1: A positive appropriability effect is less likely to exist when the firm retains a high proportion of its ex ante sales. Proposition 2: A positive appropriability eflect is less likely to exist in the presence of high sales growth. Proposition 3: A positive appropriability effect is more likely to exist in the presence of trade-oflfs between product and process R&D than in the presence of complementarities. 66 III. EMPIRICAL FORMULATION AND RESULTS This section applies empirical analysis to the above hypotheses. First, I summarize my data sources and structure. Then, 1 specify the empirical models for each hypothesis and estimate them using statistical methods. A. Data This study uses a relatively recent set of survey panel data developed by the Industrial Research Institute/Center for Innovation Management Studies (IRI/CIMS) fi'om their Annual R&D Survey. The survey encompasses a wide array of information on R&D expenditures from a large cross section of industrial firms. One hundred six corporations participated in the survey, collectively accounting for a large percentage of formal R&D in the United States. The information was collected at the firm, industry segment, and laboratory level beginning in 1992. The data used for this study is annual information covering fiscal years 1992 through 1997, reported at the firm level. It contains information on total firm R&D expenditures and on the type of R&D undertaken. This includes product R&D, process R&D, basic research expenditures, applied research expenditures, support R&D, and external R&D. The data also includes figures on annual sales. In addition to the survey data, Compustat market valuation data was appended for each firm in the survey. This includes each firm’s stock market value at the end of fiscal 67 year, the value of its tangible assets (book value), annual advertising expenditures, and annual sales. Compustat also supplied total annual R&D expenditure data for each firm in the [RI survey. In all but a small number of cases, figures for R&D expenditures and sales as reported from each source tied-out to within a small degree of error. A number of firms surveyed did not provide complete responses in any given year, and many did not respond at all in some years. Therefore, the survey data contains a number of missing data points. This raises the question of whether the non-responders were chosen randomly. If not, estimates of coefficients on any regression will be biased. Fortunately, Compustat supplied information on total R&D, sales, market value, and asset value for many of the missing and non-missing observations in the survey. A comparison of each variable from each source revealed, with one exception, a similar distribution for data reported in the survey with that of data not reported in the survey but supplied by Compustat. The one exception is total R&D. The average value of R&D expenditures supplied by Compustat is 26.5% higher than survey R&D. This may indicate that firms with higher R&D expenditures were less inclined to respond to the survey, which would imply that estimated coefficients on R&D-type expenditures using survey data alone might be biased downward. However, the survey data includes firms with a wide range of R&D expenditures, with a standard deviation twice as large as the sample mean. This suggests the sample of survey R&D expenditures adequately represent the R&D expenditures of firms in general. Summary statistics of survey responders and non-responders are depicted in Appendix E. In order to arrive at a consistent sample data set to use for each analysis below, a 68 number of adjustments were made to the original data. First, obvious reporting errors were corrected. Second, two firms were omitted from the sample because of reported average sales in excess of $100 billion, which were nearly twice as high as the next highest sales figures. Omitting these two firms considerably mitigated heteroskedasticity. Third, advertising expenditures were missing for a large number of firms for some or all years. Therefore, instead of excluding these observations, I employed an instrumental variables approach to estimate the missing values. Advertising expenditures were predicted based on the firm’s sales, total R&D expenditures, and tangible assets. Sales was chosen as a variable because it is assumed that the purpose of advertising is to increase brand awareness and therefore sales. Total R&D expenditures and tangible assets were chosen based on Doyle (1994, p. 86), who employed a similar technique to estimate advertising expenditures. First, I run regressions including only those firms reporting advertising expenditures using the following specification: ADV*i,t = 0'13: + ,3] Sale-St: + '52 Sale-92m + ’63 RDi,t + .54 TAi,t+ 6i,t , [11} where ADV“ represents advertising expenditures of firm i at time t, Sales“ represents sales revenue of firm i at time t, Sales2 1"; is sales revenue squared, RD“ represents R&D expenditures of firm i at time t, and TA i, t represents tangible assets of firm i at time t. Then, I use these estimated coefficients to compute a firm’s predicted advertising expenditures for those firms not reporting advertising expenditures. I also tried the following specifications: 69 ADV}; = at: + .31 Salem + .32 501852 + .63 RDi,t + [34 TAi,t + 81;: . [3-1’] ADVi,t = ai,t + fl! 501631;: + .32 RDi,t + 6‘i,t , [31”] Results did not differ significantly, although I used specification 3.1 because it yielded a moderately higher adjusted r-squared. Fourth, 13 firms did not report disaggregated R&D information for any year. Although employing an instrumental variables approach to estimate the missing values as I did with advertising expenditures was considered, there were not enough instruments available to estimate them all. Therefore, these firms were excluded. Furthermore, four firms were excluded because they reported disaggregated R&D information for only one year of the survey and reported zero process R&D expenditures for that year and zero expenditures for at least one other R&D type. This is significant because less than 5% of all firms surveyed with multiple observations reported zero process R&D expenditures in each year they participated in the survey. In addition, only a small minority of firms reported zero expenditures for more than one type of R&D in any given year. Given this, I find it extremely likely that these four observations are unreliable. Finally, although the majority of firms were matched to their Computat market valuation for each year 1992- 1997, a small number did not have market value information appended for either 1992 or 1997. Therefore, since the primary unit of observation in each analysis below is the five- year average for each variable included in the analysis (see the next section), a computation of the average market value would be biased for those firms that do not have 70 market values recorded in the first and last years of the survey. Omitting these firms ensures the average market value for each firm in the regression is computed using the exact same time frame. Finally, a number of firms did not have R&D information for each year of the survey. Some firms were excluded based on more than one of the above criteria. However, R&D information is extremely stable from year to year for the overwhelming majority of firms. Therefore, to preserve as large a sample as possible, these firms were not excluded. What remained was a sample of 71 firms. Tables 1, 2a, and 2b furnish summary information for relevant variables before and after exclusions. 71 Table 1. Stunmary Statistics: Before Independent Variable Based Exclusions ($MM) # Mean Std Dev Minimum Maximum Obs Market Value 83 $10,816 $15,574 $61 $73,929 Total R&D 83 $268 $429 $4 $2,251 Adverfismg 83 $482 $623 $79 $3 157 Expenditures ’ Sales 83 $8,654 $1 1,461 $6 $63,554 Tangible Assets 83 $3,038 $3,776 -$322 $17,630 (Book Value) Process R&D 75 $32 $49 $0 $200 Product R&D 76 $150 $306 $0 $1,624 Applied R&D 75 $55 ‘ $1 14 $0 $634 Basic R&D 77 $9 $25 $0 $134 Technical Service R&D 77 $27 $47 $0 $255 Notes: Computed from average firm data over 6 years of survey. All survey firms with valid reported aggregate R&D information are included. Only firms with non- missing market value data in years 1992 and 1997 are represented. 72 Table 2a. Summary Statistics — Sample Data after Exclusions ($MM) # Mean Std Dev Minimum Maximum Obs Market Value 71 $9,500 $12,407 $61 $51,681 Aggreg. R&D 71 $225 $362 $4 $1,526 Adve‘fismg 71 $467 $583 $79 $3111 Expenditures ’ Sales 71 $7,991 $10,593 $6 $63,554 Tangible Assets 71 $2,869 $3,601 -$322 $17,630 (Book Value) Process R&D 71 $33 $50 $0 $200 Product R&D 71 $ 124 $250 $2 $ 1,400 Applied R&D 71 $49 $1 10 $0 $634 Basic R&D 71 $9 $25 $0 $134 Technical Service R &D 71 $28 $48 $0 $255 Notes: Computed from average firm data over 6 years of survey. All survey firms with valid reported disaggregated R&D information are included. Only firms with non-missing market value data in years 1992 and 1997 are represented. 73 Table 2b. Summary Statistics by Year-Sample Data ($MM) 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Average Aggreg. R&D Exp. $212 $231 $219 $235 $237 $257 Average Advertising Exp. $332 $337 $358 $423 $488 $502 3:1:ng Market $6,824 $7,255 $7,407 $9,210 $11,652 $14,916 Average Firm $7,594 $7,494 $7,578 $8,322 $8,859 $8,776 S1ze ($Sales) Average Ratio R&D/Sales 5'7 4-9 4-2 3.8 3.8 3.9 Tangible Assets $2,726 $2,657 $2,862 $2,912 $3,098 $3,166 Average Product $104 $124 $103 $98 $106 $191 R&D Average Process R&D $29 $44 $29 $28 $34 $38 Average Applied Research R&D $27 $32 $31 $50 $41 $70 Average Basic Research R&D $8 $12 $1 1 $9 $10 $15 Average Technical $37 $38 $37 $28 $30 $30 Service R&D Notes: Computed from firms included in final sample dataset (71 firms). 74 B. Estimation and Results 1. Empirical Framework The following analysis derives the basic empirical equation used to estimate the returns to innovative activity. It is based on a stock market valuation approach. The stock market value of the firm is an excellent proxy for long-run expected profit because, based on traditional financial analysis, it is assumed that the market accounts for all relevant information about the firm’s expected future profitability, including the firm’s investment in R&D. I follow common practice and use R&D expenditures as a proxy for innovative activity. Therefore, the stock market valuation approach relates R&D investment to the stock value of the firm. If the stock response to R&D is positive, the market should believe that the expected profitability of R&D investment is positive. In the market valuation model, the firm’s problem is to maximize the discounted value of its future income streams (profits) while accounting for risk. Its market value is a function of the assets it holds, both tangible (TA) and intangible (IA). Let V(*) represent the firm’s value fimction. Generalizing equation 13’ 16512344,, 42. ......) . [13’] yields, 75 Vi,t =fi,t(TAi,t»1Ai,t: Riskw) . [3-11 Tangible assets refer to physical capital, which can be measured as the book value of all assets held by the firm. Intangible assets comprise knowledge stock and marketing stock. Risk is represented by the firm’s beta. Therefore, I can derive the following expression for the value of the firm: Vi,t =f( T4131. 4451',» K5231. berattl). [32] where KS represents knowledge capital, and MS marketing capital. As discussed in Chapter 1, the true functional form of equation 3.2 is unknown. For reasons outlined below, I choose to follow Doyle (1994) and use a linear approximation and apply a linear Taylor expansion to equation 3.2. This yields Vi,t = fio + fl] T413: + flz M521: + .63 K513: + fl4 b81013: + at + n + 5i,t- [3-31 The coefficients on each asset variable represent the value response to a change in the level of that asset. The parameter it captures any time series effects that may influence affect market valuations of all firms equally across time. The parameter ai represents potential unobserved heterogeneity that may result from variables conceivably omitted from the model, and can be considered an individual effect for each firm cross section. If the model is perfectly specified, at will be zero and will drop out of the equation. If the 76 model is not perfectly specified, as is likely the case (few models are) then a central issue is the treatment of (1,, the individual effect from each firm cross section. If one uses longitudinal data, as I do in this study, the statistical treatment of the individual cross section effects is crucial to the analysis. Unobserved heterogeneity can arise fiom many sources. For instance, the population of interest in this study is all firms who innovate. However, the sample being used may not be representative of this population. The sample excludes many innovating firms based on several factors: firms who do not perform formal R&D, firms not in the survey, firms not operating on well behaved financial markets, and firms in the survey but not reporting complete information (these omissions may indicate self selection bias). Another, perhaps more important, source of unobserved heterogeneity is the omission of a relevant variable. For instance, the market may include information in its valuation equation that is not accounted for in the variables in equation 3.3. Indeed, some specifications in the literature have specified a different and/or broader concept of intangible assets. In addition to the variables specified in 3.3, they have included one or more of the following: earnings, market share, industry concentration (C4), debt, patents, and firm growth rate. My specification assumes most of the explanatory power fiom these other variables reside in the variables included in 3.3. However, it is possible some information is not accounted for by the included variables, and thus reside in the fixed effect parameter ai. If these unobserved effects are constant over time, and unrelated to the other variables in the model, then ai effectively can be ignored, and pooled ordinary least 77 squares will provide consistent and efficient estimates. However, more than likely the effects are related to the other variables in the model, in which case a,- must be dealt with in another way. Several statistical techniques are available to estimate equation 3.3. The primary focus of each method is to transform specification 3.3 into one that eliminates the fixed effect parameter can One common method of doing this is to first difference the equation. If the effects are constant over time, the fixed effect parameter a,- will drop out of the equation. One advantage to Doyle’s methodology is that equation 3.3 can be first- differenced easily. Doing so yields, AVi,t = ,5] ATAz‘,t + .32 AMSi,t + ,53 AKSi,t + 13445810“ + Al’t + Vat, [3-4] where A refers to annual changes in each asset. In addition to the elimination of the fixed effect parameter ai, first-differencing equation 3.3 has several other benefits. First, it alleviates problems pertaining to the creation of appropriate measures of intangible capital. In equation 3.3, because marketing and knowledge capital are measured as stocks, “the amount of knowledge (capital) held by the firm prior to a given point in time is unobservable, and therefore the total amount held an any particular time is therefore unobservable” (Doyle, p. 62). Therefore, using changes in knowledge and marketing stock in any given year, represented by the amount of R&D and advertising investment in that year, avoids this problem. In the absence of first-differencing, marketing and knowledge stocks would need to be constructed from current and past observations of 78 advertising and R&D. This involves inferring depreciation and growth rates of intangible capital flows, which adds another level of complexity to the estimation process and introduces more opportunity for error.33 A related issue involves the relatively short history of the dataset, which impairs the construction of reliable measures of the stock of intangible capital.34 One drawback to first differencing is that it assumes the fixed effect is invariant over time. If there is a time element to (If (such that it becomes a“) then first-differencing will not eliminate it from equation 3.3, and the coefficients will be biased. Before proceeding, it is necessary to discuss the treatment of risk in equation 3.4. Risk is an important issue when valuing assets with the stock market. Although the beta coefficient is used as a proxy for systematic risk in equation 3.4, it is unavailable for estimation purposes. However, research has indicated that with regard to the beta, “the stability increases as the length of the estimation period increases — betas are relatively stable for periods of four or more years” (Doyle (1994) p. 62-3). This implies that over the course of 4 or more years, the average change in the beta is expected to be zero. For this reason, I make one further transformation to 3.3’. I average each differenced variable in the model over five years. This results in estimators ,Bj, sometimes referred to as ’3 For instance, one such method would be to assume knowledge stock equal to current R&D expenditures divided by the sum of the depreciation rate and growth rate; STOCK = R&Dt /(6+g). For more details on estimating capital stocks from intangible flow variables such as advertising and R&D, see Hall (1990). 79 between estimators (W ooldridge, 1995) that use only variation between the cross section observations. Essentially, it is the OLS estimator applied to time-averaged data: AV“; = Ar“ + ,6] ATA *1: + ,62 AMS“; + ,83 AKS*,' + ,B4Abeta*i + vi, [3.5] where the ‘*’ refers to 5-year averaged first-differences. The advantage to specification 3.5 is that the average change in the beta over five years is expected to be zero, and thus the beta drops out of the equation.35 Furthermore, the averaged data may alleviate the impact of extreme values that are often associated with survey data. After dropping the beta from the equation, 3.5 becomes: AV*,~ = Art + [7] ATA *,- + p2 AMS*,- + p3 AKs*,- + vi, [35’] Unfortunately, if beta is not stable over the 5 year period and it is omitted, then equation 3.5’ will be misspecified, and to the extent that beta is correlated with the variables included in the model, the estimated coefficients of the included variables will be biased. One would expect the beta to be most correlated with R&D expenditures 3‘ Another common treatment for unobserved heterogeneity is to use “fixed effects” estimation. This technique was employed by Ben Zion (1984), Hall (1993), and Johnson and Pazderka (1993). Instead of first-differencing, this method essentially demeans each cross section by estimating the difference of each variable from its cross section mean. The advantage to this method is that it effectively uses time series data and maximizes degrees of freedom in the regression. However, it still does not correct for time- dependent unobserved heterogeneity. Furthermore, it would be necessary to derive intangible capital stocks. 80 because they are subject to great uncertainty. However, as Doyle points out (p. 63), it is more likely that R&D intensity, as measured by R&D expenditures as a percentage of firm size, would be correlated with beta rather than the absolute level of R&D expenditures themselves. However, I find no evidence that the average change in R&D intensity is significantly different than zero.36 Because first-differencing the data redefines marketing and knowledge stock in terms of annual changes, I can use annual R&D expenditures and annual advertising expenditures as proxies. Substituting these into equation 3.5’ yields AV*,‘ = 217* + ,6] ATA *i +fl2ADV*i + fl3RD*,' + vi . [3.6] This is the basic equation used to estimate the retums to innovation. In this expression, AV*,° represents the average annual change in market value over five years for firm i, AT A *i represents the average annual change in the book value of the firm over five years for firm i, ADV*,- equals average annual advertising expenditures over 5 years for firm i, and RD"‘i represents average annual R&D expenditures over 5 years for firm i. As is customary, an intercept term is included. The change in knowledge stock, or R&D expenditures, can be disaggregated firrther into various types of R&D investment. Let ‘Process’ represent process R&D, ’5 Because the beta is omitted, fixed effects estimation would treat it as an omitted variable and add the variation of beta to the fixed effect parameter ai. For comparison, Appendix C contains fixed effects estimates for each regression below. 81 ‘Product’ represent product R&D, ‘Applied’ denote applied R&D, ‘Basic’ denote basic R&D, and ‘Service’ represent support service R&D. Equation 3.6 now can be expressed as: AV = Ar“ + a1 ATA“ + a2ADV* + a3 Process* + a4 Product“ [3.7] + a5 Basic“ + a6 Applied* + a7 Service* + e. (The ‘i’ subscripts are dropped for convenience.) Again, each variable represents a five- year average annual change. In this expression, each coefficient represents the stock response, or the marginal value, of an additional unit of input. The data includes firms from multiple industries, both manufacturing and nonmanufacturing. Compustat-provided SIC codes range from 1000 to 8700. Therefore, accounting for industry effects is an important issue. In the analysis below, industry dummy variables were included to account for industry effects. However, preliminary analysis indicated that industry terms were not significant, nor did they significantly alter the coefficients of other included variables. Therefore, to preserve degrees of freedom and alleviate collinearity, I omitted industry identifying variables from the final regressions . Another issue often present in firm level cross sectional data is heteroskedasticity related to firm size. Heteroskedasticity occurs if there is a large disparity between the 3" The average annual change in R&D intensity as a percent of the average R&D intensity is very close to zero (1.0%). 82 largest and smallest observations in the sample dataset. In this case, the error term in an ordinary least squares regression will have different variances associated with the different sizes of the observations. F inn size in the sample dataset summarized in Table 2a, as measured by sales revenue, ranges fiom $5.7 million to $63.5 billion, a significant disparity. Therefore, heteroskedasticity is likely to be present in the analysis. For each regression, a Park test was used to test for heteroskedasticity, which consists of first running an ordinary least squares regression, and then regressing the residuals against the suspected proportionality factor (either sales revenue or tangible asset value). If heteroskedasticity was detected, a weighting scheme was applied to correct for it. Then, the Park test was rerun on the weighted regression to validate the weighting scheme. The weighting scheme is described in detail in Appendix B. 2. Preliminary Analysis Grabowski and Mueller (1978) estimated after tax returns on R&D expenditures of between 15 and 20 percent based on depreciation rates of between 5 and 20 percent. Research that is more recent has used a depreciation rate for R&D capital stock of 15 percent. Other research has estimated that R&D should be capitalized by the market at between 2.5 to 8 times the investment (Hall, 1998), with most estimates centered at 5 to 6. That is, a dollar invested in R&D should increase the market value of the firm by 83 between $2.5 and $8. These figures are based on the use of flow-type variables to represent intangible capital, i.e., R&D expenditures per year. Alternatively, knowledge capital stocks can be constructed from current and past R&D expenditures and used in place of the flow variable. These knowledge capital stocks typically are 4-5 times higher in magnitude than the corresponding flow variable, and thus yield coefficient estimates approximately 4-5 times lower than the flow variable coefficients. This is consistent with an average annual return of 20 percent on R&D capital investment.37 Another empirical result is that the stock of R&D is valued at between 0.5 to 2 times the value of tangible assets. Before estimating the hypotheses derived in Chapter 2, estimation of equation 3.6 will provide a basis for comparing the returns to innovation using my sample to earlier results. The results of regressing equation 3.6, AV*,~ = Ar“ + ,6] ATA *,- +flZADV*,- + ,B3RD*,- + vi. [3.6] are summarized in Table 3. ’7 From Chapter 1, market value is defined as the net present value of current and future income. Therefore, net present value of a $1 investment in R&D, assuming constant annual returns, is equal to I/(1+k)+I/(l+k)2+I/(1+k)’+I/(l+k)‘+... +I/(l+k)T, where I represents per period income (cash flow) generated from the R&D investment. In the limit, this simplifies to Mt. Therefore, V(RDS)=NPV=I(RDs)/k, where RDs represents knowledge stock. A simple computation for knowledge stock used by Hall (1993) is RDS=RD/(6+g) where 5 represents the R&D depreciation rate and g represents the R&D growth rate. This suggests V(RD5)=I(RD,)/k(5+g). Following Hall, assume a 15% depreciation rate and a 5% growth rate. Also assume a required rate of return of 20%. Inserting V=$5, k=.2, 5=.15 and g=.05 and solving for I yields an annual nominal cash flow/income of $0.2 from a $1 R&D investment, 3 reasonable cash flow. Note that a larger depreciation rate will result in a higher annual cash flow. 84 Table 3, regression ii, indicates that the stock response to R&D is 4.7, implying that a dollar invested in R&D is worth $4.7 to the market value of the firm. This figure is well within the range of previous research. In addition, estimates of tangible assets between 1 and 2 are also within the expected range. A note of caution; the regression of equation 3.6 used the standard dataset of 71 observations. If I add back the observations excluded because of missing disaggregated R&D, I obtain an expanded dataset of 83 observations (the combination of survey data and Compustat data resulted in a fewer missing observations for total R&D than for disaggregated R&D). The results of regressing equation 3.6 with this expanded dataset indicate a smaller stock response to R&D, approximately 3.8 (regression iv), although still within the range of previous research. The response to tangible assets is moderately higher than before, and the stock response to advertising expenditures is almost unchanged. These results add confidence to my chosen statistical methodology. For further comparison, I ran ordinary least squares estimates on first-differenced variables for individual years. The results of these regressions can be found in Appendix D. 85 Table 3. Value of Aggregate Assets Ordinary Least Squares Analysis Regression Standard Data Expanded Data (# Obs=71) (# Obs=83) Dependent . . . . Variable Unwerghted Weighted Unwerghted Weighted 1 11 111 IV Interc t -400.55 -909.73 -390.92 -349.33 61’ 265.78 356.00 266.80 341.07 ATangible 2.048 b 1.234 0 1.590 b 1.448 a Assets 0.815 0.669 (0.624) 0.513 5.577 a 4.663 b 4.845 a 3.790 a “”31 R&D 0.589 0.557 (0.515) 0.433 1.395 a 2.338 a 1.707 a 2.049 3 Ad“ ExPend' 0.495 0.226 (0.398) 0.152 F Value: F Value: F Value: 66.68 gage; 52.11(1 131.72 a a 2121:1223 Adj R2: 0.687 Adj R2: 0.740 Adj R2: 0.706 01823' " Significant at the .01 confidence level. b Significant at the .05 confidence level. ° Significant at the .10 confidence level. Notes: Standard errors below coefficients. For each regression, the dependent variable is the S-year average annual change in market value. heteroskedasticity-corrected. 86 Weighted statistics are Although numerous studies have examined the returns to aggregate R&D, to my knowledge no study has examined the stock value of disaggregated R&D. The results of regressing equation 3.7, both weighted and unweighted, are summarized in Table 4. The weighted results indicate that the stock response to product, applied, and basic R&D are significantly different from zero. However, the basic R&D response is negative. The stock responses to process R&D and technical service R&D are not significantly different from zero. Applied R&D appears to be valued the most by the market; a $1 expenditure indicates an increase in market value of approximately $15. In contrast, basic research is valued the lowest, with an expected change in market valuation of $-29 for each $1 invested in basic R&D. These results paint a somewhat different picture than the results from regressing aggregate R&D. The expectation is that a rational firm will invest in each asset to the point where the marginal value of each investment is equivalent. However, this does not appear to be the case with regard to investment in different R&D types. It appears basic research and process R&D are not valued by the market, whereas product R&D and applied research are highly valued. What might explain these disparities? One possibility is that basic research is considered riskier than later stages of innovation and the market generally discounts basic research more than other types of 87 intangible assets. This also raises the possibility that unobserved heterogeneity related to risk is much more correlated with basic research and process R&D than other variables, and thus the coefficients are biased. Therefore, it is possible that an omitted variable is causing bias. One candidate for an omitted variable is the growth rate of sales and industry specific indicators. However, the inclusion of these variable did not significantly alter the results. Another possibility is that basic research is more characteristic of a public good, and therefore firms may have difficulty appropriating the returns from basic research. Finally, reporting errors may by influencing the results. Public policy measures such as the R&D tax credit provide incentives for firms to report non-R&D investments as R&D, and many government contracts are associated with basic R&D. Therefore, it is quite possible that R&D expenditures are overstated, or the cost of investing in basic research is less than the cost of investing in other types of R&D because the government reimburses basic research expenditures. Comparing process R&D and product R&D, it is evident that product R&D is valued more highly by the market. This is not surprising from the standpoint that the majority of firms invest more heavily in product R&D than process R&D. As Table 23 indicates, firms invest on average 4 times more in product R&D than process R&D. Applied R&D is the next most heavily invested type of R&D, and thus its high valuation is not surprising. In summary, it appears the market values more highly those intangible assets that are closer to the “back-end” phase of the innovation process, such as applied R&D and 88 product R&D, presumably because the returns from these types of R&D are more easily appropriated. Although the statistics are corrected for heteroskedasticity, the regression does not explicitly control for firm size. Therefore, it does not test for the Schumpeter hypothesis; i.e., a relationship between firm size and R&D value. If the market incorporates firm size effects into their valuation, equation 3.7 would not capture it. In the next section, I test for size effects. 89 Table 4. Value of Disaggregated Intangible Assets Ordinary Least Squares Analysis -- # Observations = 71 Regression Independent Variable Unweighted Weighted i ii Imme t -338.913 , 577.292 1’ 183.143 251.023 . 1.58385 , 0.85815 ATang‘blc ASSC‘S 0.65486 0.65 843 -14.81394 b -6.37705 Process R&D 6.68049 6.81091 4.30335 , 4.91704 “0‘1““ R&D 1.21591 1.33121 . 19.18513 , 15.00427 Apphed R&D 2.50408 3.14081 . 3.91657 7.34025 Tm" gem“ R&D 5.40542 5.86822 . -14.22789 29.34434 Ba“ R&D 8.95988 10.57552 2.04972 , 2.06155 Ad“ ExPend‘ 0.39300 0.29935 F Value: 58.5 7 a F Value: 88.29 ‘1 Adj R2: 0.852 Adj R2: 0.897 ’ Significant at the .01 confidence level. " Significant at the .05 confidence level. ° Significant at the .10 confidence level. Notes: Standard errors below coefficients. annual change in market value, AV“. corrected. 90 The dependent variable is the average Weighted statistics are heteroskedasticity- 3. Appropriability Eflect In this section, I test for the existence of the appropriability effect. According to hypothesis 2, process innovations should generate more net revenue than product innovations as the sales of the firm increase. This should translate to higher valuations for process R&D than product R&D as sales increase. In order to test for this effect, it is necessary to estimate the impact of R&D on firm value at different levels of firm sales. If the stock response to process R&D is larger than the stock response to product R&D, as sales increase, then I will have evidence to reject the null hypothesis that the appropriability effect does not exist. To accomplish this empirically, I incorporate sales-intangible asset interaction terms into equation 3.7 for each intangible asset variable. This yields, AV = Ay+ 6!] ATA + a2 ADV + ,62 Sales*ADV + (13 Process [3.8] + ,B 3 Sales *Process + and Product + ,64 Sales *Product + a5 Basic + ,65 Sales *Basic + a6Applied + ,66 Sales *Applied + a7 Service + ,67 Sales *Service + s. This methodology is based on Doyle (1994), with the difference that I am using disaggregated R&D data. The use of interaction terms allows me to determine the influence of sales on each intangible asset variable by examining the cross partial 9l derivative of the market value change with respect to sales and the intangible asset of interest: 62mm = 6], [3.9] oTSales)o"j where j represents a particular intangible asset, and 6]: its sales interaction coefficient. The parameter 6]- represents the stock response to an intangible asset controlling for firm size. In other words, it represents the change in the value of an intangible asset in response to an increase in sales. For example, if j represents process R&D, then the impact of an increase in sales on the value of process R&D would be represented by the coefficient 63. A positive value of 63 implies that the value of process R&D increases with firm size, while a negative coefficient implies firm value declines with firm size. The results of regressing equation 3.8 with ordinary least squares are summarized in Table 5. They indicate that the addition of sales interaction terms changes the interpretation of several intangible asset relationships. For example, the sales-process R&D interaction is positive; as sales increases, the value of process R&D increases. The coefficient is significant, so I can reject the hypothesis of no relationship between sales and process R&D. In contrast, the sales-product R&D interaction term is negative, although insignificant. Therefore, I cannot reject the hypothesis that there is no relationship between firm size and product R&D. Taking these two results together implies that the value of process R&D increases with firm sales at a higher rate than product R&D, exactly as the appropriability effect predicted. Based on this result, I can 92 reject the null hypothesis that the appropriability effect does not exist. However, the large negative coefficient for process R&D implies investment in process R&D may not be rational for all firms, depending upon their size. The responses to process R&D investment and other types of intangible investments at the mean of firm size are depicted in Table 5b. The Table indicates that both process and basic R&D have negative responses at the mean. In the case of process R&D, firms with sales below $12,403 million will not see positive returns to their investment. For basic R&D, firms with sales greater than $503 million will not see a return on their investment. Examining the other coefficients, with the exception of advertising expenditures, the value of all other assets decline as sales increases. This implies that, in general, there are decreasing returns to R&D with regard to firm size. This contradicts the Schumpeter Hypothesis. Previous research on the Schumpeter hypothesis has been inconclusive. For example, Doyle found evidence in support of Schumpeter’s hypothesis in some industries but not in others. One explanation for these findings is that Schumpeter is supported only for some types of R&D, but not for every type. Therefore, research that has used aggregate R&D to test for the Schumpeter hypothesis were dependent on the composition of R&D in the sample used. My results also may be influenced by the period I am examining. The 1990’s saw high valuations for small and growing high tech firms, which may have increased the value of intangible assets for smaller firms. However, another explanation is likely. Notice that, with the exception of basic research, the stock response to process R&D, at just under $8.4, is lower than other R&D responses. Therefore, the fact that 93 Schumpeter’s hypothesis is not supported is not surprising given that, as firm size increases, the only R&D type that benefits is the type with the lowest valued R&D. 94 Table 5. Value of Disaggregated Assets Controlling for Firm Size Ordinary Least Squares Analysis: # Observations = 71 Regression Independent Variable Unweighted Weighted 1 11 Intercept 2:632: £33.83: ATangible Assets 3:25:22; 3233):: Process R&D -3223?) £3326: (Process R&D)*(Sales) 3333,21 3333? Product R&D 323:2: 33333? (Product R&D>* 33331333? 31333313? Applied R&D 22123332 3323333 (Applied R&D)*(Sales) 000003293? 000022822 Tech. Service R&D 23:33: 1:383 (Tech. Serv. R&D)*(Sales) 333333; 0.0535(5)??? BasicR&D $213333 131i???) (Basic R&D)*(Sa1es) $3333) -3333; Adv. Expend. 8.30866) 3.3832 (Adv. Expend>* o>tm>tow 2:. m _ .N ZOFEQZOU m0 ZOF<>EmQ < XHQmem< 117 APPENDIX B 118 APPENDIX B HETEROSKEDASTICITY CORRECTION AND TEST To control for heteroskedasticity, I used one of the following two weighting schemes, each assuming that sales is the pr0portiona1ity factor. One scheme uses log transformations and the other does not. I assume an additive form of heteroskedasticity in which the estimated variance of the disturbance, 62,, takes the form: , ~. 0'2,(a) = a0 + a, SALESi + azSALESZ, [B1] or 62.05) = b, + b, log(SALES,) + bzlog(SALESZ,) [132] where a0, a,, a1, b0, b,, and b2 are constants to be estimated. In some cases, a, = b2 = 0. In each of the analyses above, I estimated the least squares equations, then apply the least squares method to the following equations: e2,~(a) = 60 + c, SALES,- + CZSALESZ, + v, [B3] ifI assume B1, or e2,-(b) = d, + d, log(SALES,) + dzlog(SALESZ,-) + vi [B4] 119 if I assume BZ. e2i(a) and e2i(b) are the ordinary least squares residuals obtained fi'om equation B1 and B2, respectively. This yields initial estimates of 62,: oil-(a) = co + c, SALESi + c,SALEs2, [B1 ’] 021(1)) = d, + 6, log(SALES,) + d,log(SALEs2,) . [B2’] These initial estimates of co, c,, c2, do, d,, and (12 are not asymptotically efficient because vi is heteroskedastistic. Therefore, another round of estimators are obtained by applying least squares to: £3,011): _c2_ +6, SALES,+c,SALES2, +v‘, [B5] 0211a) 021(3) 021(8) 0'21 (a) and e_2,{b)=_<_:9_ + c,16g(SALES,)+c,16g(SALEs2,) +v', . [B6] oil-(b) oil-(b) 0211b) 021-0) These estimators are asymptotically efficient. Thus, the ‘second round’ estimators of 0'21: is: 021(3) = c’, + c’, SALES, + c’ZSALESZ, [B1’] and 120 021(1)) = d’. + d’, 16g(SALES,) + d’,16g(SALEsz,) . [B2’] Asymptotically efficient coefficients for the specifications in each hypothesis are estimated using 021(a) or 021(b) as weights. After each hypothesis was estimated using the weighted least squares approach, I tested for any remaining heteroskedasticity using a Park test. This entails regressing the residuals obtained fiom the weighted least squares estimate against sales: 0021: 136 + B: SALES] + 81 [137} where 002, are the weighted least squares residuals. A significant B, indicates the presence of heteroskedasticity. In each regression specified in each hypotheses in Chapter 3, little or no heteroskedasticity was detected after the weighting scheme was applied. 121 APPENDIX C 122 -=: v.82 om. Sow omdemv Ewan: 3.33 3.83 2.82 was“; 283 8.82- 3mm. 8.32- nmdomm- come 3.32- 38: 3.33.. 8.83. 3.2.3 3.52 3.6me $.88. 83“; 29; Shanon. madame cod—on- $.32»- 348mg vodmnm- o3: omdvmm R. _ Nov aodw: Sdom— 3mg? N932 mmamfir one: 2.32.- $.24; $.38. mmdoom- 34.23 mwdmmm- :o: 2.6va 3.33 3.2.: 2.232 3.3? 3.32 .388, 22: 3.823- 828$. 3.3%. 2.8mm- $.38 Same—m- 3nd Sb.— Emd :06 3.0m 82. Sqm cued om. ._ mam mm _ ._ >Q< 3:6 m. n... Nae.» vmm.m $0: «3.3 88.2 :m.m_ no; 2 _._ «om.» m _ mm «a: 89m at: ogd mm: ._ 2.5.. EON NS; omod 3o.— n36”. maxi E5; Mum—.2 934.. mmmi 2.52 35.2 www.mm mmmé. 95mm 8::— .7309 wnmvd Somd $4de 36—8 :88 c: .o 2 and 2.36 wwb _ .o 3.33 mm _ .o a; afi : 2: 2 334 88.. ommmd on: £36 Sofi— wm$.~ 33.. So.— 8582 woméfi 8622:. 38.33. 26.32. 85280 832:3 x x x ._280_m:om 88:88 6.28830 .5 X x x x x x x _m:==< 80285 x x x x X 8.5 x x x x x x 823.63 2 c. o m N. c m w m N _ 6:280 :222wom 23830 mmwnmELE ESE covcwaxm 1 mcoimoawox flootm BxE ._ O 8.35 mZOBmmEOmM mHUmmn—m DmXE U XEZmAE< 123 124 ._o>u_ ..o 2: a 8.32.:ch 2865 E8 3925 4:20:38 323 30:0 @3235 .EE 2: mo 02? 6x38 95.3% 2: m_ 033:; 289.3% 2; ”8qu :22 363% 3.33 3.th m: .2 3.»me $.02: 35> :2 m 8.2 mm 33.0. 3.33 ~33: wowfl 3.2% 38— :6ch ac. _ mmv 33m: fuzz; 3:va 3.32 8:35 mamvm 2.32 now: mm. _ «.2 8.32- wme 3.23. I o_ m m o w v m 033:3 :Bmmewom Eon—anon:— Gzzouv .5 2an .32 3 2: .a cosmoc.:w.m 286:. £8 962m 45.0508 322. 323 Havana .EE 2.. .o 2...; .829: use-So» 2.. m. 0.2.2:; Eovcoaon 2:- “882 mam. v3.3. 5..me 3.6mm. 33m. 3.9.: omdow 358w 2.. mm v8.23 wmvvm modvow madam ..N. m ovdwmm 3.8. 3.32 mmdomv mmdmm. vam. 3.2.: Nag-mm ombwo> 8ch 5.5mm .3... modmmm 3.55- 33.. ”v.3.“ vim. 3:50. 3.33. 36mm. .38. 3.33. 5.3.. 3:3». 32% 8.3m- $3. 8.0%- v. .wvm . - 83-. 2.68- v. .N. 95-3. 2.83 3.2-N... ..wm: .ndmvv vmdmw was“; wnmom 3.3m..- flow. exam;- modoom- 3mm. o. 6.3- 38. ...-.03. cvdowm .oNom. ovdv. . mmdnmv 33mm 8.8.» . Ea. 2.2.91 33.. ....Nmmm- mmdmom- monm. No.33- mwom. omdmo. 36mm». NNdwN. omNm. . $.82. omdmw Nfimu> o8... Elbow- codobo 8.5 . h- 8.33-- oflh. we. . SN- mmad Eb. mood mmwd .mm.m Sod S..N m2; .2... Ema 98.. >D< mafia. covd ~36 v56 woman .86 mm»... 2:. 30... m5..m mend nwmd a... owwd SA... ammm mom. «we. mmmd wood cvm.m oz... may. god 5. .c. 036. .m . .o 306. 3.3. mom... 308 c. ..b. ccwdm v2.2 -.<-..Oh mmmd 5mm... 3:. m. ..o and an... mead 3:. m3 .o 32. mid X X X .28“. 25.2.2.2. Etom -... 8:555 X X X X X X X 32:5... 3322:. X X X X X E... x x x x x x 83903 .. o. a w .- c n v m m . H25.50 20.383”. :vnso ...-nae... 3:3. 65.28% I 20.32qu Bootm. next. .NU Baa-r 125 an. 8%; 8.5;. Nm.§n,_ «2:; 3%? 2.8a ”new 2.5:- .2.$E~ 5...»va- E.c~o_- 93mm 8.38. as; 2:. manna 8,33 033 8.82 2.83. 2.2m 3m: $.85... cams-Nu 8.3%- aévm- $ch $.32- as; :8. 2.3.8 «35‘ as: 8.82 8.2.3 8.»: a: 8.8%., 3.94% 93:5. NONE”- $02 58$. 83; SE 3&8 8.3m... 5...me , 3.2-2 3.22 gm; ~22 $82-- 58: 3.9.8.... 2.3%- Evnm ESQ- 85> 883 880d 8086 883 258.0 S885 0886 882 «885 8890 383 mm4o< . mm4 X X X APEOU «:oficogo?5. atom x x x x x x x Eecmm 58.2:— x x x x x E: x x x x x x Ems? : S a a n o w v m m _ “2.230 Same-aux :vuso ”:nmei mELE fihwtcgm | mcofimohwom flow-Cm cox; .MU czar—- 126 . o>o _.o 2: E 8:8E:wfi 8365 E8 335 456508 323 288 2%:me .85 05 mo 2:? 8x35 95-on 2: m. 032:; 2532.2” 2:_- ”862 :3: $6va 3.2 _m 3&9; 2.83 3.83 wad—o— mNaOM $.28 wodmmcm ~58: MON-mom 39mm mmdoo. 3.83» ommm. ovgvmm Emma: ”Add; 2.92 3.3% 3.23 manvm 3.2-\- oc. Scam 3.33. 3.2: mmmom 3.3m- 338» I S a w o n v m 032:; :28”:me 2032.85 APEoUv .mU Ens-r 127 omwmwo 3.003 ....nmvm ao.~00. 3.3-... 3.3% v....vo. no.3..- oo.~vvv- no. .N0- .... . mmv- av. .3 . - 8.33 h . .w. .m- $.80. 30.? v0.58 8.00.0 mm. . mm. .v. .om. m0.m~mv 3.3.. om.0vv. - 004.0. 0- 3.00m . - vvdmmw- o. .mmmm- 00.38 86v. m- mo.8> mmdowo 8.33 3.2 mm 3.2... ., mm.v.~. va. . vov vN.m0.. cavnmv- «Gan..- 8...va- b0dmm0- WEvE-N- .v.v§-w 023...- 9.8% 2.00 $04.. N0m.m .34 vav mom. mmvd wand 3m.— owmd mum.— oZ-vm 80d. Nada «3.6. 30.5 03... v28. 8nd. mid wmmd. 000.2 >Q< Sag-N .mwdm mvmdm 000.0“ . .. imam Sag-m n36. ..o..m .vw.mm 0506a Nahum www.mv- N006. awovv- . .Ndm 0Nv.0v- 0.. ...w wowav .093 03.00 .0. .3 av... . .- 0.95 $06. 2»... v0nd. Ema. avnd. 03.0. o.0.~. v. N... 30.». N30. vomv. ..vm..m >30- o.v.o.. .0m.om- mmvfi 000.2.- 000..- vm0.m.- v2.3- wvh..m- .260- 83.0w «and. m0~d 000.3 056 30.0. mafia m0m..- mvvd. 0om.w h. Wm. .20 wmmdm .mNdm 80.2 nmv.0m v3.0.- O0v.wm mam-0m ~.m.>0 ovmdn 3.60 mmm.nn 023...... omav m.n.m .36 Eva and «N0... SQN 0ov.v van m.m.v mmo.m 2....v 00v... . 00w.0 mvms. 300 2.6.0. 2.0.0. vvws m.w.v. 0006 20.3 8:00.. no. .m. 02.... 38.3 0o~.v. mwmv. «Ev. 02-6 2.5... GEN. mom... 0v.-.N. 20.2 man... wvvd. vomd- ovwv. vmm.wm- o0v.0- ...v..- 3.0.3. 090m- omfioT 382. 050.0 . RN... 050... m3... 9.0.0 vmmd 0mm... v~0.o ammd 0.0.0 ammo v3. 8:. 03d .30.. vm0.m w . v. . 9...... ”3.. av0.. mmo. mam. <-_- ~30: . v00. 80 8.88- 52%.- 38.2... 52.00 o.00..m> x x x .280 .50530 3.0m -... 8.5 x x x x x x x .0352 38.2... x x x X x 0...“. x x x x x x Ems... .. o. a w h 0 n v m N . H22:5 20.3.033— m man-BO MKNEE... 2:... 0.005% .- 2232me 88.5 08.... .v0 0.0.; 128 €3.50. .v0 07....- ..25. .... 2.. ... 8:3...Ew5 0.8.0:. 2.8 000.2% .58....08 322. $8.0 0.005% .E.... o... -.o 2...; .805: 0.5-...... o... m. 0.00.2? 250530 2% .882 9.8. 5.22 .38. 8...... was... 2.. . .... .38. ~22... 8.88 8.38 .58. .353 .55. 3.3: 8.8.. .58. 2...... m 2.8% 3.8: 382 mm. . N... ...... .. 3.8.- .38.- ..oie- 8...: .- NS...- 333 2......- was; .8... 2.28 $.83 2.2... ......N. 5.8% 2...... .863- 3.3%- 3.3.. ..dém- m2...- 3....§ $.28- 85> _ .. ... a w o w v m 2.2.5 _ 5.32me .505305 . 129 _. 0000.0 00. 00.0 00000.0 00.000 00000.0 00 . 00.0 . 0.00.0 . 0.00.0 00. 00.0 00 . 00.0 00. 00.0 8.00 00000.0 . 0000.0 00000.0 00000.0- 00000.0 00000.0- 00. 00.0 00000.0 0. 000.0- 00. 00.0 00000.0- $0.200 0.0.00 .0000 000.00 000.00 000.0 .00.00 000.00 000.00 .0..00 000.00 000.00 8380 0000.- 000.00- 000.0. 000..- 000.00 000.00- 000.00- 000.00 000.0 00..00 000.0- . 00 .000 00000.0 00.000 00.000 00.000 0. .000 00000.0 0 0 .00.0 0. .00.0 00 .000 0. .000 3.00 00000.0 0-0.00.0- 00000.0 00000.0- 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 0 . 000.0 00000.0 00000.0 .00..0“? 000.00 000.0. 000.00 00040.. 000.00 000.00 0.0.0. .0000 00.0. 000.00 000.0. 02.30. 000.0- 09.00 000.0- 000.00. 000.00- 0.0.00 000.00 000.0- 000.00 000.00- 000.00 . 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 m200 00000.0 00000.0 0. .00.0 . 0000.0 00000.0 00 . 00.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 $2680 000... 000.0 000. .. .000 000... 000.0. 0.0.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 8:080 0000.- 000.0 000.00- 000.0 0000.- 0.0..- 000.0 000.00- .000 000.0- 000.0 00.000 00.000 00.000 .0.00.0 00.000 00.000 00.000 00.000 .0.00.0 .0.00.0 .0.00.0 8.00 00000.0 00. 00.0 0 . 000.0 00000.0- 00000.0 00000.0- . 0.00.0 00 . 00.0 00000.0- 00 .00.0 00000.0. $88.0 000.00 .00..0 000.00 000.00 0.0.00 000.00 .0. .00 000.00 000.00 000.00 00.00 ...-.0880 000.0- 0.0.0- 000.00 000.00 00.... 000.0 . 0.0.0- .000. 000. . 0 000.0. 000.00 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 . 000.0 0. 0.0 000.0 000.0 000.0 <0 000.. 000.0 000.. 000.0 000.. 000.0 . 000.0 .00.. 000.. 00... 000.. 000.0.0. 000.0.0 2.8.2:. 000.0000- 000.0000- :ootoo 0.00:; X x x .280 2605000 .380 -c. x x x x x x x anecmm. 2.8.8:. 00 x x x x E .. h. x x x x x x 20.03 : 2 a 0 0 0 0 0 m N _ ”220.0 5.3203. 0 00HBO ..0n2Er. 0:5”. 050520 I 80.08.03. 380.0. .50.“. .00 2000 130 .0 00:000.:06 0.8.0:. 0:8 000000 0:22.008 30.00 0.8.0 0:00:80 .95. ..0 2.. .EE 2.. 00 o:.0> .8008 0:0-.000 2.. m. 200...? 200500 2.0 ”8.02 00.0000 00.0000 00.0000 00.0000 00.000. 00.0000 00.000. 00.0.; .00. 0 00.0000 .0000 00.0000 00.000. 00000 0. 0.0. .0.0.00 00.0000 00.0000 00.0000 00.000. 00.0000 00.000. 00.08» 00000 00.0000- 00000 0.0000- 000000- 00000 00. . 00- .0.0000 00.0000 00.0000 0.0.00 00.000. 00.00 . 0 .0.000. 00.080 00000 00.00. 0- 00.00 ...00.0- 00.000- 00.00 ...0000- 0.0000 00.000 00.0000 00.000. 00.000. 0.0000 00.000. 00.0o> 00. 00 .0.0000- 00000 .0.0.00- 00.0.0- 00000 0. 00.0- 0.0000 00.000 00.. .00 00.000. 00.00. .0.0.00 00.000. 00.080 00000 00.00.0- 00000 00.0000- 00.0.0.- 000.0 00.0000- 00.0000 .0.0000 00.0000 .0.0000 00.000. 00. . 000 00.000. 0 0 .00 > 00. .0 00.0000- 00000 00.0000- 00.000 . - 0. 0. 0 00.000 . - 00000.0 0 .0000 00000.0 . .0000 00000.0 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 . .0000 0 .0000 . .0000 8.00 .0 .0000 0 .0000- . 0000.0 0.0000 00000.0- 0.0000 0 0000.0- 00000.0 00000.0 . 0000.0 00000.0 _.>0.< _0000. 000.0 000.0 000.0 .000 0.0.0 00.0 000.0 0. ..0 000.0 000.0 >Q< 000.0- 00. .0. 0000.- .00.0 000.0. 000.0 ..0.0 000.0.- 000.0 000.0 00. .0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 . 0000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00.00 00. .0.0- 00000.0- 000.00- 00000.0- 00000.0- 00000.0- 00000.0- 000 . 0.0- 00000.0- 0.0.0.0- 00000.0- 0.0.000. 000.00 000.00 0.0.00 00.00 000.00 0.0.00 000.00 . 0.000 000.00 00.000 0.0.. 0 2000. .00000. 000.00. 000.0: 000 .00. 000.000 00. .00. 000.00. 000.00 . 000.00 000.00. 000.00 . . . 0. 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 . 0.00.:0> 5.08.03. E00533. 3.2.8. .8 0300 00.0.0 0. .00 0000.0 000. .. .0000 000.. 00.0.0 0000.0 0000.. 0000.0 .00.. >D< .000.00 0000.0. .00000 0.00.0 0000.00 00.... 0000.0. 00.0.0. 0000.0 0000.0. 00.0 j000000 0000.00 0000.00 0 . 00 .0 0 00.0.00 000.00 0000.0. 0000.00 0 . 00.00 0000.00 000. .0 2000. 000.00- 0000.0 0000.00- 0.00.00 000. .00- 000.00 0000. . 0 0000.00 0000.00 0000.00 000.00 . 000.0. .0.0.0. 0000.0. 0.0000. 0000.0. 00.0. 0000.0. 0000.0. 000.0. 0000.0. 000.0. 8380 0000.0. 00. 0.0- 0000.0 000000-. 0000.0 000.00- 0000.0- 00 . 0.0. - 0000.00- 0. . 0.0.- 000.00- . 0000.0. 0000.0 0000.0. 0000.0 00.0.0. 000.0 00. 0.0 ..000. 0000.0 0000.0. 000.0 02.00.0 .00000 00. 0.00 0000. .0 0000.00 0000.00 000.00 . .0000 0000.00 0. 00.00 .00000 0 . 0.00 . 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 00000.0 .00000 00000.0 00000.0 0.0000 0 0000.0 00000.0 00000.0 8:080 .0. 00.0 00000.0 00000.0 0.0. .0 00000.0 0000. .0 000 . 0.0 0000.0 0. 00.0 00000.0 0000. .0 000880 0000.0 000.0 0000.0 .0000 0000.0 000.0 0000.0 0000.0 00.0.0 0.00.0 000.0 8:080 0000.0- 000.0. 00.0.0- 0000.0 0000.0- 000.0 0.00.0. 0000.0- 0000.0 0000.0- .000 00 . 0 .00 0000.0. 0000. . 0 0000.0. 0000.00 .000. 0000.0. 00. 0.0. 0000.0. 0000.0. 000.0. 0080 . 0 000...- 00000.- .00. .0.- 00.0.00- 0000.00- 000.00.- 00000.- 0.00.00- 0000.00- 0000.00- 0.0.00- 00000 0.000 0000.0 0000.0 .0000 0 .00 0000.0 0000.0 00000 5.00 000.0 <0- 0000. . 0000.0 .0000 00.0.. 0000.0 .00.. 0000.0 000. .0 0000.. 000. .0 0 00. . 00.00.. 0.0.0.0 8088:. .0..000- 000.000- 5880 o.00..0> X x x .880 800.8000 .0..00 .5 5:0 x x x x x x x .0:::< .0088... x x x x x .8... x x x x x x 0.0.03 : o. a 0 0 0 0 0 m N _ ”25:00 8.8803. 0 00n000 ..0n08.0 0.8.0 0:00:80 1 0:23.803. 088.0. 000.0 .00 0.000. 2 .03. ..0 o... .0 3:02...ch 0.8.0:. 2.8 0009.0 0.5.8.008 30.2. 22.5 0.00.5.0 dz... 2.. ..o o:.m> .8208 .05-.80 2.. m. 200...? 200.5000 2...- ”8.07. 0. .0. 00.0.00 00.0.00 00.0.0. .0000. 00.0000 00.00.. 00.80» .0.0000 0000.0 00.000 00.0000 0.000 0000. 00.0000 0000. ...00.0 00.0000 00.00. 0.000. 00.0000 .0..00. 00.080 00.000- 00.00. .- 0. .0000- 00.00 00.0.0.- 00.0000 0000.0. 00. .000 00.0 .00 00.0000 00.000. .0000. 00.0000 00.0.0. 00.8> 00.00- 00.00.0- 00.0000- 00.00.- 00.000.- 0.0000 00.000... 00.0000 0.0. .0 00.0000 00.000. 00.000. 00. . 000 00.0.0. 005; 00.0.0- 00.000- 00.000.- 00.0000- 00.000.- .0.0000 00.00. .- 000000 0000.0 .0.0000 00.000. 00.0.0. 00.0000 00.00.. 0023.0 00.000.- .0.0000- .0.000.- .0.0000- 00.000- 00.0000 00. .000- 00.0000 00.0000 00.0000 00.000. 0.000. 00.0000 00.00.. 00Eu> 00.00.0- 00.0000- 00.0000- 00.0000- 00.0000- 0.0000 00.000- . . 0. 0 0 0 0 0 0 200...; 00.3203. 200.5000... €0.50. .00 0.00...- 3 8288 8888 828.8 828.8 8288 88.8 888.8 828.8 828.8 828.8 8.8.8 3:8 838.8 888.8- 8288 888- 828.8 88.8. 8_8.o- 8288 888.8. 8888 88.8- .332 888. 88.: 88.8 8.: 3.8.8 82: 88.: 88.8 88.: 88.8 88.: 88.2 88.2 88.8 68.8 8.2: 88.8 8.8: 828 88.8 888 88.: 888 . 888.8 888.8 288.8 888.8 88.8 888 888.8 888.8 888.8 888.8 28.8 N ..Smmmm 888.8 :83. 888.8 88.8 888.8 88.0 888.8 8888 388.8 8:8 883 .8885 88.8 888.0 888.8 888.8 88.8 $888 88.8 88.8 8888 888.8 888.8 885 88.8- 88.? :88- 8887 888- 88.8- 888- 82.8- 82.8- 888- 883- .3805 8888 888.8 888.0 888.8. .8888 88.0 3888 888.8 888.8 288.8 88.8 8.8 8.8.8- 888- 88.8- 88.8- 888- 88.8. 888.8- 8888- 88.8- 88.8- 8_8.o- .8805 88.: 28.: 85: 88.: 88.2 8.: 88.: 88.2 88.: 88.: 8:: .885 88.: 8:8 888 8:8 88.; 83.8 88.; 888 88.: 88.8 88.3 _888.o 8:88 8888 8:88 2888 E88 8288 8288 828.8 8:88 888 3.8 3288 «888- 8288 888- 8888 88.8- 8.88- 888.8- 888- _88.o- 888.c- .382; 788.: 88.8 88.8 88.8 888 888 88.8 38.8 88.8 88.8 838 $89: 88.:- 888- 88.2- :88- 888- 8.8.- 88.8- 8:3: 88.8- 88.2 88.- 88.8 88.0 88.8 288 88.8 82 :88 £88 888 8.2 88 5 8:; ENE 88: 888 88; 85 882 m8... 888 88.. 83 882 888 88.35 8 88- 88 m8- flow-ECU Eng-ax) x X X ._otou Eon—Egon 3:8 -5 x x x x x x x Edna E853— x x x x x 5.8 x x x x x x 2825 : 2 o w 8 o n v m N _ 82:5 coaewom 8&8 EH25; 85E Emu—Sew I 8.28.er $0th taxi so 038. 134 .82 3 8:835 82,; g ._o>o_ _.o 05 8 8585ch 88:8: 2.8 3.55 456508 323 823 Havana .EE 05 oo 02? 8th.: 86-on 2: m_ 033:; Enocooou 2F ”8qu Shook-o $.33 mvdofi. goof €833 m: _ m _ “93> 2 RV vodmmm aflov Nvdmv Nomwm 3.85 omomvc mod _ vm 8880 mos-om. Gooom acou— @033» «when $.m2 m- 3va 3.8.2- omoom 8.2 m 3.3% wodhmm @333 8.22 no. _ oov 3.8: 388, an? o _ .vam- 3.88 8.33 - ofi mm 3.98. 3.5-nun 3.3mm no.3 _ o ovowm _ modoov omooo— 328$ 55on Summon- omomm 8.32- gm?- mmdo— .- 868m vooomm ._ c. _ now $.32 8.2-3 coda: no.8; onmm nip-Ev- ommmm . 3.9.:- oommm ”:5;- vnooom otmmvm Somoo 3.2.2 369% tumm— _ No.8; 3on o figme- oooom 3.3 _ m- 3on 3.30- vmmoooo om _ ooo.o ommoooo _ o _ ooo.o ommoooo o_ooo.o mm _ ooo.o vw _ooo.o _o_ooo.o 2. _ooo.o o _ ooo.o 8.5m .mooooo omoooo- vmooooo onooooo omoooo- .ooooo mooooo- envoooo 3886 mm _ ooo.o w o ooo.o *>Qo< 336. mm. fig mow-ed- ommwo vomodm God 35d of: ._ T om. _.m- vmowi onmo ownmooo vwomooo $386 on _ mooo onomooo cmmooo mvomooo mi moo-o mummooo t: mood Nomooo 37% 983.? m _ vooo- oco_o.o- nmvvooo mow .o.o- vomooo mmvooo- “Ko— o.o- omovooo oofloo- mvvooo tumm— EZ-dv $3.3 m2 m5. 089% 2.3.3 oomwm «gown 883% «2 wow 02 wém Soov 28m $32 23.3 213 momvom Eo—N v8.8. 23:3 3.3: 2 5.3 omoi M: flow . mwfiooo m _ flood ooiooo omflooo mo_moo.o S—ooo mmEooo ooSoo.o mom—ooo omo_oo.o om_oo.o 88m Eovooo mocmooo hmwvooo Elooo- ommvooo vooooo- onvmooo mow—ooo Smooo- monoooo Smooo- ...SEom hmvmfiv mmmvém mmnmov momodm mommom 55.3” oofldm 3.2.3.. mummdm nonfimm mvoom 838m wmmmdv- 2“.me Swoon- omfl .mn- 38.3. 32:.- owtdm- $31. 33.3. wfloo moo. _ v- . I o_ o o N- o n v m m _ 033:; p.282?”— E28882: 6.258 .8 033. 135 APPENDIX D 136 ._o>o_ _.o 2.: a oo=SE=m_m 28:2: m=ou BREW .E2quoo 323 32.5 Emu—Em .EE 2: oo 2:? .819: €0-on E. a 032:? Eat—.38 2:. ”882 Bad , won? 2 mo umvo ommo mwno «MW—o w _ mo ommo hmmo >Q< on?“ _No..m mono Now.“ 3.6 N26 29o vmmo BEN Nona wow; Sn; Sod mono mmwo mono Emo nmvo Nmoo mono 00mm MEN”: «3.2 «San , . ovmw 56.— ohoo Nov; Goo nmmo Eco- 4<+Oh omwo own; mono Fvo Nmno Evo ammo N_m.o mono Motto 5. «Rd vmno Now; ovoo So..- 2.0.7 SN..- 33. gm; on 8132 3:63 omoémv Sodom Soomm ommgmm 3.053 oomo: ”:33 mvmsom 385:: www.moE n. Swami- _om._o_. ooooom- 333$ gnomm- SNoE- movon- www.mmm- mafioom- I ooumno I oonmno I Sumac I oonmno r ohnmEO Wolmwo 3E9?» WWIMHWO BEwEoB Wolwmwo BEBE: whimwwo BEEP: whimwo 32.32: 033”; o E . 3 E: u E . 3 é: o E . 3 ..5 u E . 3 .2: c E . >9 .:3 E235 No 3.8 3-3 3.3 voéo 8-8 _ 2232»; BEE Enos—3m I 50> Eomm 5o mzoawewom moss—um 3.84 92:20 .0 2an wow—3mg yam; AHQE D X_OZmnE< 137 APPENDIX E 138 Table 1. Summary Statistics-Responders and Non-responders ($MM) All 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Years The following variables were supplied by both the IRI survey and Compustat Avg. R&D Exp. Survey Resp. 326.5 219.0 354.3 334.6 195.8 386.8 449.2 (# Firms) (46) (46) (5 8) (60) (67) (57) Non-Resp 483.5 437.0 376.7 436.9 785.9 473.1 417.4 (# Firms) (56) (54) (44) (41) (36) (41) Advertising Survey Resp 180.3 150.5 202.0 119.9 76.8 279.8 240.1 (# Firms) (46) (46) (58) (60) (67) (57) Non-Resp 223.0 213.1 187.7 242.1 383.2 115.7 194.5 (#Firms) (60) (60) (48) (46) (3 9) (49) Market Value Survey Resp 1 1878 9048 9174 8949 8393 14279 20352 (#Firms) (40) (42) (53) (54) (61) (50) Non-Resp 11795 8397 9062 9710 16714 14069 15133 (#Firms) (54) (5 3) (42) (41) (34) (41) Firm Size ($Sales) Survey Resp 1 1369 8960 1 1742 1 1865 7923 13632 13474 (#Firms) (46) (46) (5 8) (60) (67) (5 7) Non-Resp 12262 1 1912 9999 1089 18463 1 1399 1 1474 (#Firms) (56) (55) (45) (44) (3 7) (45) Ratio R&D/ Sales Survey Resp 4.4% 3.3% 3.2% 3.0% 3.3% 8.3% 4.1% (#Firms) (46) (46) (5 8) (60) (67) (5 7) Non-Resp 11.1% 8.1% 8.2% 23.6% 14.8% 4.7% 7.3% (#Firms) (5 6) (54) (44) (41) (36) (41) The following variables were not available from Compustat All 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 Years Product R&D 161.9 107.8 241.5 ’ 171.2 88.1 106.2 265.2 Process R&D 47.1 27.2 46.0 80.4 27.4 36.6 61.0 Basic Research R&D 10.7 8.5 10.7 10.2 8.5 11.1 15.0 Applied Research 46.2 34.2 34.6 46.8 44.3 47.2 68.3 R&D Technical Service 40.3 34.0 36.7 42.8 26.1 53.2 48.5 R&D 139 REFERENCES 140 REFERENCES Acs, Z. and DB. Audretsch (1987), "Innovation, Market Structure, and Firm Size," Review of Economics and Statistics, 69(4), Nov., pp. 567-74. eds. (1991), Innovation and Technological Change: An International Comparison, The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI. Altshuler, Rosanne (1988), "A Dynamic Analysis of the Research and Experimentation Credit," National Tax Journal, 1988, v41(4), 4453-66. Anderson, E. and D. Schmittlein (1984), “Integration of the Sales Force: An Empirical Examination,” RAND Journal of Economics, 15, 385-95. Arora, Ashish, Ralph Landau, and Nathan Rosenberg, eds. (1998), Chemicals and Long- Term Economic Growth: Insights from the Chemical Industry, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York. Athey, S. and A. Schmutzler (1995), “Product and Process Flexibility in an Innovative Environment,” RAND Journal of Economics, v26(4), pp. 557-74. Athey, S. and S. Stern (1998), “An Empirical Framework for Testing Theories about Complementarity in Organizational Design,” NBER Working Paper No. 6600. Audretsch, D.B., Albert Menkveld, and A. Roy Thurik (1996), The Decision Between Internal and External R&D,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, V152, 5 19-530. Austin, David H. (1993), “An Event-Study Approach to Measuring Innovative Output: The Case of Biotechnology,” American Economic Review, v83(2), 253-258. Bernstein, J .I. (1986), Research and Development, Tax Incentives, and the Structure of Production and Financing, University of Toronto Press, Toronto. Burton, Peter S. (1994), “Product Portfolios and the Introduction of New Products: An Example from the Insecticide Industry,” RAND Journal of Economics, v25(1), 128-140. Calantone, R.J., C.A. di Benedetto, and B. Sriraman (1994), “Examining the Relationship Between Degree of Innovation and New Product Success,” Journal of Business Research, v30, pp. 143-48. 141 Capon, N., J .U. Farley, D.R. Lehmann, and HM. Hulbert (1992), “Profiles of Product Innovators Among Large US. Manufacturers,” Management Science, v38(2), 157-168. Chesbrough, H.W. and DJ. Teece (1996), “When is Virtual Virtuous? Organizing for Innovation,” Harvard Business Review, 74(1), 65-74. Clark, KB. and SC. Wheelwright (1993), Managing New Product and Process Development, The Free Press, New York. Cohen, W.M. and S. Klepper (1992), “The Anatomy of Industry R&D Intensity Distributions”, American Economic Review, v82(4), 773-799. (1996), “F inn Size and the Nature of Innovation Within Industries: the Case of Process and Product R&D,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, v78(2), pp. 232- 43. Committee for Economic Development (CED) (1980), Stimulating Technological Progress, The Heffeman Press Inc., New York. Collins, EL. (1981), “Tax Incentives for Innovation-Productivity Miracle or Media Hype?," Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 4(1), 68-74. Cordes, J ., H. Watson and J. Hauger (1987), "Effects of Tax Reform on High Technology Firms," National Tax Journal, 40(3), 373-92. Crawford, R (1991), In the Era of Human Capital, HarperCollins Publishers Inc., USA. Deiaco, E., E. Hornell, and G. Vickery (1990), Technology and Investment: Crucial Issues for the 1990's, Pinter Publishers, London. Dennison, E. (1985), Trends in American Economic Growth, 1929-1982, Washington: Brookings, p. 30. Dowrick, S. ed. (1995), Economic Approaches to Innovation, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, UK. Doyle, T. (1994), “Firm Size and the Returns to R&D Investment in High-Technology Industries,” MSU Doctoral Dissertation. Ebrill, LP. and D. Hartman (1983), "The Corporate Income Tax, Entrepreneurship, and the NonCorporate Sector," Public Finance Quarterly, v11(4), 419-36. 142 Encaoua, D, B. Hall, F. Laisney, and J. Mairesse (1996), The Economics and Econometrics of Innovation: An Overview,” from the 10th International ADRES Conference and NBER. Freear, J ., J. Sohl, and W. Wetzel Jr. (1994), "Smaller Company & Inna-entrepreneurial Issues: The Private Investor Market for Venture Capital," Engineering Management Review, 22(3), Fall, 91-97. Geroski, P. (1989), “Entry, Innovation, and Productivity Growth,” The Review of Economic Statistics, 572-578. Geroski, P., S. Machin, and J. Van Reenen (1993), "The Profitability of Innovating Firms,” RAND Journal of Economics, 24(2), 198-211. Ginn, Martin E. (1995), The Creativity Challenge: Management of Innovation and Technology, Part B (in Monographs in Organizational Behavior and Industrial Relations), J ai Press Inc., London, v20. Gompers, Paul A. and Josh Lerner (1998), “The Determinates of Corporate Venture Capital Success: Organizational Structure, Incentives, and complementarities,” NBER, Working Paper 6725, Cambridge. Griliches, Z. (1981), "Market Value, R&D and Patents," Economics Letters 7, 1981, 183-187. Reprinted in Z. Griliches, ed., R&D, Patents, and Productivity, 1984, 249- 252, Chicago: University of Chicago Press. (1987), "Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A Survey," JEL, 28(4), pp. 1661-1707. Gruber, William H. (1981), The Strategic Integration of Corporate Research and Development, Amacom, New York. Guerard, J .B. Jr., and AS. Bean (1998), R&D Management and Corporate Financial Policy, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., NY. Hall, Bronwyn H. (1990), “The Manufacturing Sector Master File: 1959-1987,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA, Working Paper No. 3366. (1993), “The Stock Market’s Valuation of R&D Investment During the 1980’s,” American Economic Review, v83(2), 259-264. (1998), “Innovation and Market Value” NBER. 143 Hall, H., J affe, A. and Trajtenberg (1998), “Market Value and Patent Citations: A first Look,” NBER. Hayes, Robert H. and SC. Wheelwright (1984), Restoring Our Competitive Edge: Competing Through Manufacturing, John Wiley & Sons, New York. , S.C. Wheelwright, and KB. Clark (1988), Dynamic Manufacturing: Creating the Learning Organization, The Free Press, New York. Heertje, A. and M. Perlrnan eds. (1990), Evolving Technology and Market Structure: Studies in Schumpeterian Economics, The Univ. of MI Press, Ann Arbor, MI. Hines, J. Jr. (1993), "On the Sensitivity of R&D to Delicate Tax Changes: the Behavior of US Multinationals in the 1980's," in Tax Issues of the 1990's. Hirschey, Mark (1982), “Intangible Capital Aspects of Advertising and R&D Expenditures,” The Journal of Industrial Economics, v30, 375-390. Hirschey, M. and J. Weyhandt (1985), "Amortization Policy for Advertising and Research and Development Expenditures," Journal of Accounting Research, v23(1), 326- 35. Hollomon, Herbert J. (1979), “Policies and Programs of Governments Directed Toward Industrial Innovation,” Technological Innovation for a Dynamic Economy, Pergamon Press, NY, pp. 292-317. Holt, K. and J. Seetzen ( 197 5), “Innovation Research at the International Institute for the Management of Technology”, OMEGA, The International Journal of Management Science, v3(2), 219-227. Horwitz, Paul (1979), “Direct Government Finding of Research and Development: Intended and Unintended Effects of Industrial Innovation”, Technological Innovation for a Dynamic Economy, Pergamon Press, NY, pp. 255-291. Hulten, C. and J. Robertson (1984), "The Taxation of High Technology Industries," National Tax Journal, v37(3), 327-46. Hung, NM. and N. Van Quyen (1994), Dynamic Timing Decisions Under Uncertainty, Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg. Johnson, L. and B. Pazderka (1993), “Firm Value and Investment in R&D,” Managerial and Decision Economics, v14, 15-24. 144 Jorde, M. and D. Teece, eds. (1992), Antitrust, Innovation and Competitiveness, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Kamien, M. and N.L. Schwartz (1982), Market Structure and Innovation, Cambridge University Press, New York. Klepper, 3- (1996), “Entry, EXit, Growth, and Innovation over the Product Life Cycle,” American Economic Review, v86(3), pp. 562-83, Kurdas, C. (1994), Theories of Technical Change and Investment: Riches and Rationality, St. Martin's Press, New York, NY. Lee, H. and J. Stone (1994), “Product and Process Innovation in the Product Life Cycle: Estimates for US. Manufacturing Industries,” Southern Economic Journal, 60(3), 754- 781. Levin, R.C., W. Cohen, and D. Mowery (1985), “R&D Appropriability, Opportunity, and Market Structure: New Evidence on Some Schumpeterian Hypotheses,” American Economic Review, v75(2), 20-24. Levin, R.C., A.K. Klevorick, R.R. Nelson, and S.G. Winter (1987), “Appropriating the Returns from Industrial R&D,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 783-820. Leyden, D. P. and A. N. Link (1992), Governments Role in Innovation, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht. Mansfield, E. et. a1 (1977), "The Production and Application of New Industrial Technology”, Norton, New York, pp. 22-32. Mansfield, 15., “Industrial R&D in Japan and the United States: A comparative Study,” AEA Papers and Proceedings, 78, 2 (1988), 224—228. Mansfield, E. (1986), "The R&D Tax Credit and Other Technology Policy Issues," American Economic Review, v76(2), 190-94. McGrath, M. and MN. Romeri (1994), “The R&D Effectiveness Index: A Metric for Product Development Performance,” Journal of Product Innovation Management, v11, 213-220. Megnal, P. and M. Klock (1993), “The Impact of Intangible Capital on Tobin’s q in the Semiconductor Industry,” American Economic Review, v83(2), 265-269. Mil grom, P. and J. Roberts (1990), “The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: 145 Technology, Strategy, and Organization,” American Economic Review, v80(6), 995- 1 026. Morroni, M. (1992), Production Process and Technical Change, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Mowery, David. C. “The Changing structure of US industrial research: Implications for R&D organization in the Russian Federation,” International Journal of Technology Management, #5,6,7, 1994. Nelson, RR. and G. Wright (1992), "The Rise and Fall of American Technological Leadership," JEL, 30(4) Dec., pp.1931-1964. Pakes, Ariel (1985), “On Patents, R&D, and the Stock Market Rate of Return,” Journal of Political Economy, v93(2), 390-409. Palmer, Karen (1991), “Diversification by Regulated Monopolies and Incentives for Cost-Reducing R&D,” American Economic Review, v8l(2), 266-270. Pine, B.J. II, B. Victor, and AC. Boynton (1993), “Making Mass Customization Wor ,” Harvard Business Review, 71(5), 108-121. Quirmbach, HQ (1993), “R&D: Competition, Risk, and Performance,” RAND Journal of Economics, v24(2), 157-197. Ravenscraft, DJ. and FM. Scherer (1987), “Life Afier Take-over,” Journal of Industrial Economics, v36. Ricardo, David (1817), Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, 3d ed., 1821, London: J. M. Dent, 1911. Roessner, D.J. ed. (1988), Government Innovation Policy: Design, Implementation, Evaluation, St. Martin's Press, New York. Rosegger, G. (1980), The Economics of Production and Innovation: an Industrial Perspective, Pergamon Press, Oxford. Rothwell, R. and W. Zegveld (1981), Industrial Innovation and Public Policy: Preparing for the 1980's and the 1990's, Greenwood Press Westport, Connecticut. Scherer, F.M., (1982), “Inter-industr3I Technology Flows in the United States,” Research Policy 11, pp- 227-245. 146 , (1984), “Using Linked Patent and R&D Data to Measure Interindustry Technology Flows,” in Zvi Griliches (ed.), R&D, Patents, and Productivity, Chicago: University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research. and D. Ross (1990), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, 3rd ed., Houghton Mifflin Company, Boston. Schumpeter, J .A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, Harper & Brothers Publishers, New York. Shevlin, T. (1987), "Taxes and Off-Balance-Sheet Financing: Research and Development Limited Partnerships," The Accounting Review, v62(3), 480-509. Simon, H.A. (1979), "Rational Decision Making in Business Organizations," American Economic Review, Vol. 69, No. 4, pp. 493-513. Slitor, RE. (1966), "The Tax Treatment of Research and Innovative Investment," American Economic Review, v56(2), 217-31. Smith, Adam (1994), The Wealth of Nations, The Modern Library, New York, 1776. Sobek, D.K., J .K. Liker, and A.C. Ward (1998), “Another Look at How Toyota Integrates Product Development,” Harvard Business Review, 76(4), 36-49. Solow, Robert (1957), "Technological Change and the Aggregate Production Function", Review of Economics and Statistics, 39(3), 312-320. Swenson, CW. (1992), "Some Tests of the Incentive Effects of the Research and Experimentation Tax Credit," Journal of Public Economics, v49(2), 203-218. Tillinger, J. (1991), "An Analysis of the Effectiveness of the Research and Experimentation Tax Credit in a Q Model of Valuation," Journal of the American Taxation Association, v13(2), 1-29. Tirole, Jean (1990), The Theory of Industrial Organization, The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Utterback, James M. (1979), “The Dynamics of Product and Process Innovation in Industry,” in Technological Innovation for a Dynamic Economy (Hill & Utterback eds.), Pergamon Press, NY, pp. 40-65. Vijverberg, Chu-Pong, and J. Fei (1996), “Production Functions with Factor-Oriented 147 Scale Sensitivity,” The Review of Economics and Statistics”, 309-320. Zaltman, G., R. Duncan, and J. Holbek (1973), Innovations in Organizations, Wiley- Interscience Publication, New York. 148