s I. : . kw . .h-l ‘ , 7‘3... 1.21.14 in A 1.5}... .2; 3:3. :. v.1. if . :. 337...: . 3.... x . O V ‘ ;uumn..xv.. . t :4! . .1. . 5P... 2.3. ‘ g. | 1.. z Ma.“ . ,3. - auhwmmfiwwuév v. vll‘ :l . I, 2.: . . x: V .2; ha...» :3. Efmmw . ix 4. 33.3 3.2.5 3 ‘t it . I . \l O: L ,2. 3i, i. (‘1‘ ...};...)11..€ u. A c3:- . .iiJ .91.i...d.vw!..fi.ziséqa.. , 1.3... .A" ‘I‘iv‘ ‘. ‘ ll "“3Rf'lfiflcfi‘linufiun “N.-l W~> {is}: x . . :....23........5( u! v..9[.:\1.\1..u!: . Unae L... .i 1. :x ....uy~i-l..p 1. \ !..uv.o..& 1'. 7 , $.91 53...: ”Law? . . {IL A . , , . . I \uofi'uvt. Egalftfl . . I. EVE: “3. t... . . , V , 5. M .i ‘ .l . .. F r at. .2. I... t... 51.. .1. V . . ‘ l ‘ '9}. . . I III I I { I..:‘..e git; o: llBRARY Michigan State University This is to certify that the dissertation entitled THREE ESSAYS ON UNCERTAINTY AND LEARNING BY ECONOMIC AGENTS presented by Hilde Patron has been accepted towards fulfillment of the requirements for Ph.D. degree in Economics / \/{ajor prof'essor Date 5 fing/m 263/ MS U i: an Amrmau'w Action/Equal Opportunity Institution 0— 12771 PLACE IN RETURN Box to remove this checkout from your record. To AVOID FINES return on or before date due. MAY BE RECALLED with earlier due date if requested. DATE DUE | DATE DUE DATE DUE OCT 0 4 t£00L 6/01 c-JCIRC/DateDuepss-p. 15 THREE ESSAYS ON UNCERTAINTY AND LEARNING BY ECONOMIC AGENTS By Hilde Patron A DISSERTATION Submitted to Michigan State University in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY Department of Economics 2001 ABSTRACT THREE ESSAYS ON UNCERTAINTY AND LEARNING BY ECONOMIC AGENTS By Hilde Patron Based on the assumption that agent’s decisions affect their understanding of their environments I introduce Bayesian updating of beliefs in three different economic models to study how the agent’s ability to learn affects the decisions of rational agents. In Chapter 1 I study a two-period model with an incumbent firm threatened with entry. Demand is unknown and stochastic, and prices contain statistical information about demand. The incumbent’s first period decision affects the informativeness of the price level and through it, the probability of entry. Hence the incumbent can manipulate its quantity to discourage entry. In equilibrium, unless the possible demand functions differ by a constant, the incumbent always manipulates first period output to reduce the probability of entry, i.e. limit prices. In particular, if given its prior information the entrant is currently not entering, then the incumbent limit prices by concealing information from the entrant; if at current beliefs the entrant is entering, then the incumbent limit prices by revealing information. In Chapter 2 I study a model in which fiscal policy determines that for a short period of time the government must rely exclusively on the income from issuing money, but it is uncertain about the way in which monetary policy influences the public’s demand for money. I assume that at any point in time the government uses all the information available to it to make the best possible decision, and that as new observations become available the government updates its beliefs about the demand for money using Bayes’ rule. The three results of the model are: First, the government values more information about the demand for money as this allows it to make a more accurate decision. Second, if the government can affect the informational content of the demand for money (that is, unless the possible demand functions differ by a constant) it will adjust the rate of growth of the money supply to increase information. Third, under some parameter specifications the government induces a hyperinflation to learn about demand. In Chapter 3 I study the design of incentive contracts for central bankers when the government and the private sector are imperfectly informed about the central banker’s preferences. Since the contract affects the inflation rate set by the bankers, which in turn contains statistical information about the banker’s loss function, the government can manipulate the contract to increase information. However, bankers have incentives to manipulate the government’s and the public’s perception of their preferences and hence they manipulate the inflation rate accordingly, which affects the informational content of each contract and the expected variability of the inflation rate. The interaction of these two effects determines the gains and losses from inducing more transparent monetary policies, and whether bankers should be appointed to one or two periods. Copyright by HILDE PATRON 2001 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to thank Rowena Pecchenino, Carl Davidson and Thomas Jeitschko for their guidance and help in writing this dissertation. I also benefited from comments from and discussions with Chris Curran, Ana Maria Herrera, Leonard Mirman, Elena Pesavento and Ed Schlee. Finally I would like to acknowledge my parents, my brothers, my husband, Laureano, and my beautiful, sweet daughter Andrea. TABLE OF CONTENTS LIST OF TABLES ................................................................................. viii LIST OF FIGURES ................................................................................. ix INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 1 CHAPTER 1 MONOPOLY EXPERIMENTATION AND ENTRY DETERRENCE: LIMIT PRICING THROUGH LEARNING ...................................................... 4 1.1 Introduction .............................................................................. 4 1.2 Related Literature on Limit Pricing ................................................... 7 1.3 The Model ............................................................................... 10 1.4 The Equilibrium ........................................................................ 13 1.4.1 The Second Period Equilibrium ........................................ 13 1.4.2 The First Period Equilibrium ........................................... 16 1.5 An Example ............................................................................ 17 1.6 If the Incumbent Could, Would it Try to Discourage Entry? ................... 22 1.6.1 General Discussion ...................................................... 22 1.6.2 Conditions Under which the Incumbent Limit Prices ............... 24 1.7 Conclusions ............................................................................. 33 CHAPTER 2 UNCERTAINTY, LEARNING, AND SEIGNORAGE MAXIMZING GOVERNMENTS .................................................................................. 36 2.1 Introduction ............................................................................. 36 2.2 Literature Review ...................................................................... 41 2.3 Model and Equilibrium ............................................................... 44 2.3.1 The Basic Model ......................................................... 44 2.3.2 The Equilibrium .......................................................... 51 2.3.3 The Myopic Equilibrium ................................................ 52 2.4 The Value of Information ............................................................ 53 2.5 Effects of Experimentation in High Inflation Economies ........................ 55 2.6 Solution for Uniformly Distributed Shocks and Linear Demand F unctions...65 2.7 Some Intuition on the Model ......................................................... 76 2.8 Case Study: The Bolivian Hyperinflation of 1984-1985 ......................... 77 2.9 Conclusions ............................................................................... 80 CHAPTER 3 INCENTIVES CONTRACTS FOR CENTRAL BANKERS: INFORMATIONAL IMPLICATIONS OF LINEAR CONTRACTS ................................................. 82 3.1 Introduction ............................................................................. 82 3.2 The Model .............................................................................. 89 vi 3.3 Delegation with Learning ........................................................... 102 3.3.1 The Model ............................................................... 102 3.3.2 The Equilibrium ......................................................... 105 3.3.3 The Value of “More Transparent” Monetary Policy (The Value of Information) ............................................................. l l 1 3.3.4 Central Banker’s Incentives to Manipulate Information .......... 124 3.3.5 Government’s Incentives to Induce More Informative Inflation Rates (Incentives to Experiment) ..................................... 130 3.4 Conclusions ............................................................................ 143 CONCLUSIONS ................................................................................... 147 APPENDICES ..................................................................................... 150 APPENDIX A Appendix to Chapter 1 ................................................................... 151 APPENDIX B Appendix to Chapter 2 ................................................................... 161 APPENDIX C Appendix to Chapter 3 ................................................................... 171 REFERENCES .................................................................................... 183 vii LIST OF TABLES Table 2.1 Summary of Example ............................................................. 72 Table 2.2 Minimum and Maximum Inflation Rates ...................................... 74 Table 2.3 Gains in Seignorage from the Experiment ...................................... 75 viii Figure 1.1 Figure 1.2 Figure 1.3 Figure 1.4 Figure 2.1 Figure 2.2 Figure 2.3 Figure 2.4 Figure 2.5 Figure 2.6 Figure 2.7 Figure 3.1 Figure 3.2 Figure 3.3 Figure 3.4 Figure 3.5 Figure 3.6 Figure 3.7 Figure 3.8 Figure 3.9 LIST OF FIGURES Expected Demand Functions for the Example ................................. 18 Increasing Quantity Increases Information .................................... 27 Increasing Quantity Decreases Information .................................... 28 Expected Demand Functions: Case ((1) ......................................... 33 Seignorage Function with Laffer Curve Property ............................ 48 Informativeness of the Inflation Rate .......................................... 55 Conditions under which the Non-Myopic Inflation Rate is Higher the Myopic Rate ........................................................................ 56 Money Growth Paths ............................................................. 59 Hyperinflationary Money Growth Paths ....................................... 61 Spread of the Possible Demand Functions ..................................... 64 Intuitive Representation of the Model .......................................... 77 Value of Information: Restricted vs. Unrestricted Models ................ 113 How Bankers Signal their Type ................................................ 117 Value to the Central Banker of Signaling its Type .......................... 123 The Central Banker does not Manipulate Information ..................... 126 The Central Banker Increases Information ................................... 127 The Central Banker Decreases Information .................................. 128 One Type of Central Banker Decreases Information, One Type Increases Information ....................................................................... 129 Myopic reaction functions ...................................................... 134 Given the Strategic Behavior of the Bankers, Increasing the Punishment Increases Information ............................................................ 136 ix Figure 3.10 The strategic behavior of the banker induces more transparent monetary policy .............................................................................. 141 Figure 3.11 Static Loss Function of the Government ..................................... 142 INTRODUCTION When rational, optimizing agents have to make decisions without fully knowing their environments they must use all the information available to them at any point in time to make the best decision possible, they must revise their beliefs as new information becomes available and they must adjust their actions according to what they learn. Based on these premises I study how the agent’s ability to learn, and firrthermore to generate information affect the decisions of rational optimizing agents in three different models. In Chapter 1 I present a two period model of two rational, risk neutral, profit maximizing firms, the incumbent and the entrant, that face an unknown and stochastic demand function. There are two possible states of demand but firms do not know which is the true state. In the first period the incumbent sets a maximizing output, and a price and output are realized. Firms use this information to update their beliefs. If given these beliefs the expected profits of the entrant in the second period are positive the entrant enters and both firms compete in quantities, if they are negative the entrant does not enter and the incumbent stays a monopolist. Since the incumbent’s first period output affects its posterior beliefs, the incumbent can induce more informative outputs. With more information it can make a better informed decision in the second period and increase expected profits. However, the entrant starts out with the same priors as the incumbent does, observes the same variables, and updates beliefs in the same way, thus whatever the incumbent learns, the entrant learns as well. More informative outputs then also affect the expected profitability of the entrant. The incumbent can use this to its advantage to try to discourage entry. I find that the expected profits of the incumbent firm are decreasing in the probability of entry, and thus that unless the incumbent cannot manipulate the information of the entrant (that is unless each output level is equally informative), it manipulates the first period quantity to deter entry. In Chapter 2 I study a model in which the government has accumulated large deficits or has large spending needs, but it can only finance itself with the income from money creation (seignorage), for example because of the inefficiency of the tax system combined with low credit ratings. The government is uncertain about the parameters of the money demand function, and can learn about them in a Bayesian fashion. Knowing the demand function accurately is important because this helps the government determine what proportion of money issue turns into inflation and what into real seignorage revenues. I find that the government always gains fi‘om better knowledge of the demand function and thus it seeks to learn and it adapts to new information. Constant money growth rates are thus suboptimal (unless the possible demand functions differ only by a constant). Furthermore, I find that for some parameter values the government creates a hyperinflation in order to learn about demand. In Chapter 3 I study the design of linear contracts for central bankers when the central banker’s preferences for output over inflation stabilization are not fully known. Bankers are hired for one or two periods and given a contract that stipulates a punishment if the inflation rate is above the socially desirable rate. If they are hired for two periods the contract is revised after the first period. After the bankers are hired, the private sector forms expectations of inflation for the period and sets wages accordingly. A supply shock is then realized and observed by the bankers who then set the inflation rate. Based on the inflation rate, which is a noisy observation of the banker’s preferences, the government updates its beliefs and adjusts the second period contract (or punishment) accordingly. The private sector also updates its expectations of inflation and wages after observing the inflation rate. The three results of the model are: First, there exists a parameter space for which the government benefits from more transparent monetary policy (more information). For these parameters however, the bankers might not benefit from more transparency. Moreover, as long as the banker can affect the beliefs of the government it will do so, that is, bankers act strategically. In particular if the banker’s value of signaling its type is positive (negative) it will try to increase (decrease) the government’s amount of information. Second, the strategic behavior of the central banker has two effects on welfare. On the one hand it increases or reduces the informativeness of the inflation rate, and on the other hand it increases or reduces the variability of the inflation rate (and of output). Third, the interaction of these two effects determines whether the government sets contracts that increase information, and whether bankers should be hired to serve one or two periods. CHAPTER 1 MONOPOLY EXPERIMENTATION AND ENTRY DETERRENCE: LIMIT PRICING THROUGH LEARNING 1.1 Introduction Firms often face uncertainty about their environments. For example, they may not fully know their cost structure, the quality of their product, or the demand they face. If so, they might take deliberate measures to increase their information, thereby sacrificing current period profits for more information and thus future higher profits. When there is more than one firm and when information is a public good the first period decision becomes a complicated issue, as it can be used not only to learn (experimentation) but also to alter the rival firms’ perception of profits (limit pricing or predatory pricing). Thus considering two fnms introduces all sorts of dynamics into the decision making process in the presence of uncertainty. One particular case is a monopolist faced with the threat of entry, which is the topic of this paper. I present a two period model of two rational, risk neutral, profit maximizing firms, the incumbent and the entrant, that face an unknown and stochastic demand fimction. There are two possible states of demand but firms do not know which is the true state. In the first period the incumbent sets a profit maximizing output, and a price and output are realized. Firms use this information to update their beliefs. If given these beliefs the expected profits of the entrant in the second period are positive, the entrant enters and both firms compete in quantities, if they are negative, the entrant does not enter and the incumbent stays a monopolist. Since the incumbent’s first period output affects its posterior beliefs, the incumbent can induce more informative outputs. With more information it can make a better informed decision in the second period and increase expected profits. However, the entrant starts out with the same priors as the incumbent does, observes the same information, and updates beliefs in the same way, thus whatever the incumbent learns, the entrant learns as well. More informative outputs then also affect the expected profitability of the entrant. The incumbent can use this to its advantage to try to discourage entry. I find that unless the established firm is not able to affect the informativeness of the price level, it limit prices, that is, it manipulates output to reduce the probability of entry. This result is similar to Fudenberg and Tirole (1986), who found that a firm might price below monopoly to reduce the probability of other firms joining the market. In my paper however, limit pricing can mean increasing or decreasing quantity. Under some circumstances entry deterrence takes the form of concealing information (less precise beliefs), and under other circumstances it takes the form of revealing information (increasing the chance of bad news). The intuition of this result is as follows: the entry decision is based on what the entrant learns after the first period. If for example the entrant is currently considering entry, new information might reveal some bad news with more precise beliefs. Thus the incumbent can deter entry by increasing the entrant’s information. The form of uncertainty and the information generation process I study in this paper have already been studied in monopoly and duopoly situations. Among the many papers in the literature, two that are particularly important to my study are Mirman, Samuelson and Urbano (1993) and Mirman, Samuelson and Schlee (1994) Mirman, Samuelson and Urbano (1993) study the conditions under which a monopolist faced with an uncertain and stochastic demand function experiments. They find that as long as the monopolist can affect the informativeness of the price level it experiments in the direction that increases information, except for the case in which the value of information is zero'. Mirman, Samuelson and Schlee (1994) study the same problem for a duopolistic market, and find that since the value of information for the duopolist could be negative, information could take the direction of reducing information. Otherwise, firms experiment so as to increase information. In this paper I study a firm that can be either a monopolist as in Mirman, Samuelson and Urbano (1993) or a duopolist as in Mirman, Samuelson and Schlee (1994). The firm has a belief concerning whether it will be one or the other but does not know for sure which one. The formulation of my model is similar to their models, however I study how the decision to increase or decrease information depends on how the probability of entry is affected with more or less information. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 1.2 I review the limit pricing literature. In Section 1.3 I set up the model, and in Section 1.4 describe the sequential equilibrium of the game. In Section 1.5 I solve for the equilibrium of an ‘ One such case is a zero marginal cost monopolist that faces two possible linear demand functions that cross at the quantity axis. example. In Section 1.6 I study the conditions that determine whether the incumbent limit prices or not, and in Section 1.7 I conclude and discuss several extensions of this paper. 1.2 Related Literature on Limit Pricing In a seminal paper Bain (1949) suggested that prices in an industry could reveal future pricing policies or the character of the industry. Subsequent papers on limit pricing can be divided into one of these two groups. Papers that study limit pricing as a credible threat (e.g. Bain (1949), Modigliani (1958), Friedman (1979), Salop (1979) and Spulber (1981)), and papers that study limit pricing as revealing something about an industry characteristic known to the established firm but unknown to the entrant. Among the latter, the preeminent example is Milgrom and Roberts (1982). Other papers are Matthews and Mirman (1983), Harrington (1986) and Jain, Jeitschko and Mirman (2000). My paper is among this second group and for this reason I concentrate on reviewing this strand of the literature. Milgrom and Roberts (1983) study a signaling model with two firms. Each firm is uncertain about its rival’s unit costs, which can be low or high. Moreover, the price set by the incumbent contains information about its costs. Thus a price below the monopoly price could be a signal of low costs. Since the incumbent firm wants the entrant to think it is low cost, limit pricing occurs in equilibrium. Entry however is not necessarily deterred. For example, in a separating equilibrium the entrant is not fooled and entry is not deterred. Matthews and Mirman (1983) study a similar model of asymmetric information. They assume that firms know all cost functions, but that there is a persistent industry profitability parameter known to the established firm but unknown to the entrant. Moreover, there are unobservable random shocks to demand, which occur after the established firm has made its decision, and which prevent the price from perfectly revealing the industry characteristic. They find that limit pricing always occurs in equilibrium. Harrington (1986), also in a model of asymmetric information, assumes that the incumbent is uncertain about the entrant’s costs and the entrant is uncertain about the costs of both firms. If the two cost functions are correlated, the first period price conveys information about both cost structures. For example, a high price signals that the incumbent frrrn has high costs and that the entrant is likely to have high costs as well. Decreasing price thus does not necessarily deter entry. For Milgrom and Roberts (1983) and Matthews and Mirman (1983) limit pricing means charging a price below the short run monopoly price. Unlike them, Harrington finds that if the incumbent’s and the entrant’s cost are sufficiently correlated, which is reasonable if both firms have access to the same technology, limit pricing can take the form of charging a price above monopoly price. Following Harrington’s result, I will define limit pricing as any action taken by the incumbent firm with the intent to reduce the probably of entry, whether it means increasing or decreasing prices. Jain, Jeitschko and Mirman (2000) study an incumbent firm threatened with entry, but unlike my paper the incumbent firm must contract with a bank for outside funds. In their model uncertainty arises because the bank and the entrant are not sure about the incurnbent’s type (costs) but observe a noisy signal of it. They study the design of contracts between the bank and the incumbent firm, and how these are affected when the incumbent is threatened with entry. They show that the bank structures the first period contract so as to reduce the probability of why, because deterring entry increases the profits of the incumbent and thus the payments that the bank can extractz. My model is different from theirs because I do not model contracts between financial institutions and firms, and thus I do not concentrate on learning in principal- agent models. Instead I concentrate on the pure entry deterrence model among producing firms. In the above papers, as well as in other models of limit pricing, the results depend crucially on how information is modeled. In particular, it is the incentive to preserve its informational advantage which determines the incumbent’s incentives to limit price. In my model I relax the assumption of asymmetric information of any kind. I relax this assumption to study the more realistic question of limit pricing when the incumbent is still learning about its environment (demand). This adds richness to the problem because now the incumbent faces a real dilemma: given the public nature of information, if it wants its rival to learn less it has to learn less as well. 2 Iain, Jeitschko and Mirman (2000) is a modified version of the paper by Jeitschko and Mirman (2000) who study short term contracting in a principal-agent model where the principal does not know the agent’s type. They however do not consider the threat of entry. I find that even in the absence of an informational advantage, as long as firms do not fully know the characteristics of the market demand, limit pricing almost always occurs in equilibrium3. 1.3 The Model I analyze a two period game. There are two rational, profit maximizing, risk neutral firms. In period one there is only a single firm, an incumbent ( I ) that can produce at a marginal cost k, . The incumbent sets an output and observes the resulting price. There is a second firm, the entrant ( E ) that observes the incumbent’s output and the resulting price. In period two the entrant can choose to produce an identical product with marginal cost kg. The entrant incurs a small entry cost § if it chooses to produce. If expected profits are negative, the entrant will not enter and the incumbent remains a monopolist. If it enters, each firm independently and simultaneously sets output. Given the total output, a market clearing price results. In each period the inverse demand function is given by p = g(Q, 7) + a , where p is the market price, Q is the total quantity produced, and a is the realization of a random variable, whose distribution is characterized by the density function f (a ). I assume that the expected value of a is zero, that f (5) is continuous and positive and that it satisfies the monotone likelihood ratio property (MLRP), i.e. [ff—6% is strictly decreasing in a. s 3 Only when the incumbent firm cannot affect the informativeness of the price level, that is when the possible demand functions only differ by a constant, limit pricing does not occur in equilibrium 10 y is an unknown parameter that can take on two possible values, 7 e {7, z}, where the upper bar means the “good” demand and the lower, the “bad” demand, i.e, \7’Q g(Q,?) 2 g(Q, z). The function g is non-increasing in Q, and for convenience, twice continuously differentiable in Q. Finally assume that there exist numbers Q and Q with 0 < Q < Q such that g(Q, y) > g(Q, y) 2 min(k, ,kE) , that is assume that there is positive production in equilibrium. The firms do not know which is the true state of demand. However, in period one both firms have common beliefs about demand. That is, for a given output, both firms expect the same price. In particular, they have a belief p° that ytakes on the value ; . In period one, firm 1 chooses an output Q,. After the first period quantity is chosen, a random shock is realized (although not observed) and hence a price is realized. Firm [’3 expected profit in period one is, 2r,(Q,.p°> = I g(Q,,?)p° +g(Q,,z)(1- p") —k,IQ, . Assume that there are no fixed costs, that 7r, (Q1. p°) is strictly quasiconcave, and that the fimction g is such that Q g’ + 2g is strictly decreasing in Q. These last two assumptions are technical assumptions that are needed in order to ensure the existence of an equilibrium (the proof is in Appendix A). Both firms observe p and Q, but not a. With these commonly observed variables and common priors, firms update their beliefs about demand according to Bayes rule and have the same posterior. Let p denote the posterior belief that y takes on the value ; , then, by Bayes rule, 11 _ p°7 ’ p°f +(l-p°)[_ p(p:Q1) : where 7 = f(p-§) = f(p —g2 l4 which is non-negative given the monotone likelihood ratio property (i.e. according to the likelihood ratio property % is strictly decreasing in a , and thus > \ll‘fl I". I“: 97,671“). Thus fl[1440120. Cl Since entry happens for high enough prices (Lemma 1.1), there is a minimum price w (Q ,) such that if the first period price is higher than this price, the entrant enters, if it is lower, the entrant does not enter. The minimum price that induces entry is determined implicitly through Bayes rule as follows, ,0*(p Q)E pof£W(QI)—g(Qp;» ’ p°f(W(Q,) — g(Q, . 7)) + (1 — p°)f(v’(Q,) — g(Q,, z» (1.2) where p“(p,Q,) is the minimum value of the posterior belief needed for the entrant to enter, i.e. p*( p, Q,) is defined by VE(p*) a 0. Alternatively, we can define the minimum price that induces entry W(Q,) by the identity V5 ( p(l//(Q, ), Q, )) E 0. When first period price is not high enough, the entrant does not enter and the incumbent remains a monopolist. Let V," (p) denote the value function of the incumbent when there is not entry, i.e. mp) = [g(q'"(p),7)p+g(q'"(p).z_)(1— p)—k,1q"'(p), where q’" (p) is the quantity that maximizes monopoly profits for the incumbent, i.e. q”(p) e arg max [g(qiho + g(q, {XI - p) - kllq - 15 In summary the second period equilibrium is given by the quantity q’"( p) if p< p*(p,Q,) , and by the quantities q, *(p) and qg *(p) if p 2 p*(p,Q,)- 1.4.2 The First Period Equilibrium In period one the incumbent accounts for the effect of its first period decision on the informativeness of the price level and thus on future profits. Thus in period one the incumbent maximizes first period profits plus the expected discounted value of second period profits I have to take expectations of second period profits because in period one the posterior belief p is a random variable whose distribution depends upon the incumbent’s first period output and price. At the time of the maximization problem, p is random variable and thus I have to take expectations of second period profits over all possible prices. Formally, the incumbent chooses Q, to maximize, ”1(ano) H: I, o = 919;) °° 1'3 -ao V(QI) where 5 is the discount factor, and h(p,Q,) is the posterior distribution of first period price implied by posterior beliefs and by the shock a. To find h( p, Q,) let E( p, Q,) be the value of a that must result if the period one price is p , the first period quantity is Q, , and the true state of demand is ;; and let g( p, Q,) be the value of a that must result if the period one price is p , the first period 16 quantity is Q, , and the true state of demand is Z . The density of p can be written as h (AQI) = .00 7 + (1- 10°);- Intuitively, the incumbent firm maximizes first period profits plus the discounted expected value of second period profits. Expected second period profits are expected duopoly profits conditional on entry (i.e. conditional on p being at least l/I(Q,)), plus expected monopoly profits conditional on no entry (i.e. conditional on p being less than V’(QI ) ) Let Q, *(p°) be the resulting first period equilibrium quantity. The existence of equilibrium is proven in Lemma 1.2 and Proposition 1.1. For continuity of exposition I prove these statements in Appendix A. Lemma 1.2: If a period two equilibrium exists, then that equilibrium is unique and at least one firm produces a positive quantity’. Proposition 1.1: Let g(Q,y) be defined and continuous on 1R+ for 7 e {7, z}and let there be Q such that g(Q,7)=0 for 76 {7%}. Then a (possibly mixed strategy) sequential equilibrium existss. In the next section I develop an example to illustrate the model and the equilibrium. 1.5 An Example For illustration, the following linear demand example is used throughout the paper. Consider the following two linear demand functions: ‘ Mirman, Samuelson and Schlee (1994), Lemma 2, page 368. 5 Mirman, Samuelson and Schlee (1994), Proposition 1, page 370. 17 p=20—Q+£ p=20—1.5Q+£' Since for all Q>0 and all 3, 20—Q+£220—l.5Q+£, then p=20—Q+£ is the “good demand”. Graphically these two demand fimctions are shown in Figure 1.1. Assume that a is uniformly distributed in the interval [-15,]5]. The density function of a is thus given by f (a) = T5——(L—-1_5) = 310 , and the expected value of a by " a 52 ‘5 (15)2 - (-15)2 6 E(£)= j—da= = =0. _,5 30 60 _,5 60 P A 20 40/3 20 Q Figure 1.1. Expected Demand Functions of the Example ¥ 6 In general, if s is uniformly distributed in the interval [0, b], its density function is given by f (s) = b; — a b 2 b 2 2 and its expected value by 5(5) = Ide5 = 2“: )I = (12(1)- (a)) = (b :20: a) = a: b . ._ a — a - a - a 18 This example violates two of the assumptions of the model: first, that the shock has unbounded support, and second that its density function is differentiable. Although these assumptions are violated, the example retains their general implications, namely that there is no learning with probability one after the first period, and that higher prices increase the beliefs that demand is the good one (that is that beliefs are monotonic). Finally assume that 621, k, =4, k5 =8, 6:55, and p” =0.5. To find the equilibrium I first find the second period equilibrium. If there is no entry, the incumbent chooses q’” to maximize monopoly profits, which are given by It," (p) = [(20 - q’" ) p + (20 —1.5q"')(l — p) - 4] q'" , which gives maximizing quantity 64 ,and rofits V’" =____. p ’ (p) 1.5-0.5p 8 * :— q’" (p) 1.5—0.5p If the entrant enters, firms compete in quantities, and thus solve (1.1), which in Max [9(20 - q, ‘45) + (1 - p)(20 - 15(9; + ‘112)) - 414; 4! the example is given by , Agax Iprzo—q, ~q.)+(1-p>(20—1.5(q, +q.»—8Iq. -55 20 which ives the Coumot e uilibrium uantities * = , S q q q, (1)) 3,1545,» ... 8 . . 400 qE (p) = , and value functions for the Incumbent, V,( p) = , 3(1.5 — 0.5p) 9(1.5 — 0.5 p) 64 and for the entrant V = — 5.5. 50’) 9(1.5—0.5p) To find the incumbent’s expected second period value function I need to integrate second period profits over all possible posterior beliefs. With a uniform distribution, there are only three possible posterior beliefs, zero, the same prior, or one, as follows. If 19 the true demand is given by p = 20—1.5Q, +8, then the first period price is within the following interval pe[20—1.5Q, —15,20—1.5Q, +15]; If the true demand is given by p = 20—Q, +5 , then the first period price is within the following interval pe[20—Q, -15,20—Q, +15]. If the first period price is above 20—1.5Q, —15 but strictly below 20—Q, —15 , then the firms learn that the true demand is the “bad” demand. If the first period price is strictly above 20-1.5Q, +15 , then the firms learn that the true demand is the “good” one. Formally posterior beliefs are given as follows, 0 if 20-1.5Q,-15$p<20—Q,—15 p: p°=o.5 if 20—Q,—15 spszo-I.5Q,+15, 1 if 20—1.5Q,+15p f=0; and if p=l, then p°f+(l-p°)[ 1_ p°f _ p°7+(1—p°)/”(l-po)£=0' 20 i/I(Q,) = 20 — Q, - 15 = 5 - Q, . Therefore the entrant’s decision can be represented with the following rule, - 0 Entry Rule {Entry If p e {p ’ 1} , No Entry if p = 0 or by, Ent’y if pZS-Q, Entry Rule . No Entry If Otherwise For prices above S—Q, the incumbent expects duopoly profits V,( p) , and for prices below 5 - Q, , it expects monopoly profits V,"' (p). Second period expected profits are thus given by, ZO—Q, +15 2 0—1.5Q, +15 1,, ,Q V, (p =1)h(p = 1)dp + [M V, (p = 0.5)hrp = one W (Q )= ' ' ' 1 20-Q,-Is m ’ I,,_,_,Q,_,,V, (p=0)h(p=0)dp thus, 35-9, 400 1 35-159, 400 1 law-so:9(1.5-0.5(1))5dp + 5-9, 9(1.5-0.5(0.5))§dp W(Q,)= =35.6+0.13Q,. + J-S-Q, 64 1 d s-I.SQ, 1.5—0.5(0) 60 p Expected second period profits are an increasing function of first period quantity, intuitively because higher quantities both increase information and reduce entry. (More on this in the next section.) 21 To obtain the sequential equilibrium the incumbent chooses quantity Q, to maximize [0.5(20—Q,)+0.5(20—1.5Q,)—4]Q, +W(Q,), which yields the first period equilibrium quantity Q, "‘ =6.45. 1.6 If the Incumbent Could, Would it try to Discourage Entry? So far I described the model and equilibrium, and illustrated it with an example. Now I address the following natural questions. Given that this is a model with a threat of entry, how does the incumbent react to the threat of entry? That is, does the incumbent limit price? What does limit pricing look like? Does the incumbent limit price by concealing information from the entrant? Or instead, by increasing the entrant’s knowledge of the industry? And exactly, what is the definition of limit pricing? 1.6.1 General Discussion In the first period the incumbent sets a quantity Q, , which affects the function g(Q,,y) , and through it the price level p = g(Q,,y) + 8. Although the incumbent or the entrant does not observe the shock a , the quantity Q, affects the possible distribution functions of prices 7(e)=f(p-g(Q,i» and 1(a)=f(p—g(Q,._r_». and through them the minimum price that induces entry w(Q, ) , implicitly defined by, p°f(v/(Q,)-g(Qp;)) ” (”’Q’) E p°f(w(Q,)-g(Q,.?»+(1—p°>f(w(Q,)-g(Q,. _y_»’ posterior beliefs p , p°7 ,0(PIQ1)= p77:- (1_p0)£ , 22 their distribution, h (PeQI) = P0 7 + (1- POM, and therefore the probability of entry, G , formally given by G(Q,) = f, 9,) h( p, Q, )dp . If the posterior distribution of beliefs is riskier in the Rothschild-Stiglitz sense, then information increasess. Thus if changes in Q, increase information (lead to more accurately beliefs) and through more information deter entry (reduce the probability of entry), then the incumbent limit prices by enhancing the entrant’s information. If changes in Q, decrease information and through less information deter entry, then the incumbent limit prices by concealing information from the entrant. In the example of Section 1.5, entry occurs for p2 p*= 0.41, or prices above i/I(Q,) = 5 — Q, . Thus the probability of entry is given by, _ 20-1.5Q,+15 1 20—Q,+15 p0 _ I G(Q’)— Jio-Q,-15 26- I + «go-1.59”” 25 p_l-fiQ" Since the entrant enters for prices above w(Q,) = S—Q, , an increase of one in first period quantity decreases the minimum price that induces entry by one. All else constant, there are more price observations that induce entry, and thus one would expect an increase in the probability of entry. The probability of entry however goes from G(Q,) = l—éé-Q, to G(Q, +1) =l-$(Q, +1) , which means that G decreases by i, 8 This comes from the definition of a more informative experiment as defined by Blackwell (1951) and (1953). An experiment is a pair of measures [ f (p-g(Q,, 1)), f (p—g(Q,,;))] , one for each state of nature that gives the distribution of the first period price. An experiment 21 = [f ( p - g(Q, ', 1)), f (p — g(Q, ',;))] is more informative than an experiment 2. = min-g(Q, '.z)).f(p- g(Q, 2?)». if lame, ".piihrpe, )dp 2 Jame, '.p»h(p.Q, )dp for every continuous, convex function z(p(Q, , p)) : [0,1] —> 91 . 23 not increases by one. In this example, if the incumbent wants to limit price it must increase quantity. Note that not all changes in Q, that affect information necessarily affect the probability of entry, hence, when studying limit pricing I must abstract from everything other than changes in 7 and i that translate into changes in the probability of entry. In particular I will say that if the incumbent sets a quantity Q, "‘ so as to reduce the probability of entry, then the incumbent limit prices. Traditionally, the standard definition in the literature is that the incumbent limit prices if it charges a price below the short run monopoly price with the intent to discourage other firms from joining the market (as in Bain (1949), Matthews and Mirman (1983), or Harrington (1986) for example). I do not want to use this definition however, because as explained before the difference of my model and the short run monopoly might include manipulation of information that does not affect the likelihood of other firms joining the market. That is, since information may be of value to the incumbent firm, the firm might manipulate information to make a better informed decision even if this does not affect the entrant’s decision to enter or not. It seems natural thus to define limit pricing by its purpose, by any action aimed at reducing the likelihood of entry. 1.6.2 Conditions Under which the Incumbent Limit Prices To study the incentives of the incumbent to reduce the probability of entry I compare its maximization problem with a hypothetical incumbent that takes the probability of entry as constant. 24 An incumbent firm that takes the probability entry as given chooses Q, to maximize equation (1.3) subject to Egg-Q12 = 0. Using Leibniz rule to differentiate G(Q,) with I respect to Q, yieldsg, dG(Q,)=_ . h °° dh(p.Q,)d “Te, we» (w(Q.).Q,)+V(£)——dQI p. Hence the incumbent that takes entry as given solves the following problem, V(QI) to Agax e,(Q,,p°)+6 I W(ptp,Q,))h p * , then increases in information reduce the probability of entry; if at current beliefs the entrant is not entering, i.e. if p° < p * , then increases in information increase the probability of entry1 1. Formally these assumptions imply the following: Assumption A1 . 1: In any of the following two scenarios the probability of entry is non-increasing in quantity, i.e. d—Zfl s 0. 1 ALL] If increasing quantity decreases information, (Eng) <0 , and if at current beliefs the entrant is not entering, p° < p*. A1.1.2 If increasing quantity increases information, (g'—g') > 0, and if at current beliefs the entrant is entering, p° > p *. Assumption A1.2: In any of the following two scenarios the probability of entry is 5199.220, non-decreasing in quantity, i.e. sz A1.2.1 If increasing quantity decreases information, (Q— g') < 0 , and if at current beliefs the entrant is entering, p° > p *. ” This is an assumption and not a result of the model. For example consider the example from Section 1.5. If prior beliefs had been assumed to be given by p° = 0.1 then at prior beliefs the entrant would not enter and thus increases in information should increase the probability of entry. However the probability of entry dG(Q,) d 1 construct models that violate thia assumption. Since these cases do not make intuitive sense I will rule them out. in this case is given by G(Q,)=1—%:—Q, , and hence < 0. Hence mathematically it is possible to 26 A1.2.2 If increasing quantity increases information, (E'— g') > 0 , and if at current beliefs the entrant is not entering, p° < p * . The term (E'- g') gives the distance between the means of the two possible distribution functions of prices, and it is thus a measure of the amount of information. If (E'— g') is positive, it means that as quantity increases, the distance between the means of the two possible distribution functions of prices increases, and thus information increases (as in Figure 1.2). ’9 Figure 1.2. Increasing Quantity Increases Information If (33') is negative, as quantity increases the two possible posterior distributions of prices move closer together and become more undistinguishable (Figure 1.3). Increasing quantity thus decreases information. 27 (0' Figure 1.3. Increasing Quantity Decreases Information The role of (Q— g') in the assumptions (and in Lemma 1.3) is twofold. First, it determines whether limit pricing means increasing or decreasing quantity. Second it establishes a relation between the entry decision at priors and at posterior beliefs as follows. For example, if (g'—g_') s O (as in Figure 1.3), increases in quantity decrease information. If at prior beliefs the entrant does not enter (i.e. p° < p*), increases in quantity do not reveal any new information, and thus should not change the decision of the entrant. Decreasing quantity however might reveal some good news with more precise beliefs and increase the profitability of the entrant. One would thus expect the dG(Q,) p*). Decreasing quantity, which increases information, might reveal some bad news for the 28 entrant with more precise beliefs. One would expect the probability of entry to decrease as quantity decreases, 2%(91—1 2 0. 1 These assumptions, although arbitrary, have intuitive appeal. This is a model where the only reason why an entrant’s profitability might increase or decrease is through the beliefs of the entrant. Thus the only reason why an entrant might change its mind about entering or not entering is if it learns something hurtful or helpful. If given priors the entrant is entering, no news should not change its mind; bad news might. Lemma 1.3: Given assumptions AH and A12, an incumbent firm threatened with entry limit prices, that is G(Q, *) s G(Q,” ). In particular, (a) If reductions in quantity increase information, and through more information increase the probability of entry [(3— g') < 0 and ii—(QQL) s O i, the incumbent sets a quantity 1 higher than the incumbent that takes entry as given, i.e. Q,* 2 Q,” . Since this reduces the probability of entry and decreases information, then the incumbent limit prices by concealing information from the entrant. (b) If increases in quantity increase information, and through more information increase the probability of entry ((§'—§y>o and d—(jg’lzo J, then the incumbent sets a I quantity lower than the incumbent that takes entry as given, i.e. 29 (C) (d) Q,*s Q,"E . Since this reduces the probability of entry and decreases information, then the incumbent limit prices by concealing information from the entrant. If increases in quantity increase information, and through more information reduce the probability of entry [(g'-g')>0 and (Egg—030], then the incumbent sets a 1 quantity higher than the incumbent that takes entry as given, i.e. Q,*2 Q,” . Since this reduces the probability of entry and increases information, then the incumbent limit prices by revealing information to the entrant. If decreases in quantity increase information, and through more information reduce the probability of entry ((3:8) < 0 and dig!) 2 0 j, the incumbent sets a quantity I lower than the incumbent that takes entry as given, i.e. Q,* s Q,”. Since this reduces the probability of entry and increases information, then the incumbent limit prices by revealing information to the entrant. Proof: In Appendix A. 30 Lemma 1.3 states that the incumbent threatened with entry manipulates first period quantity to reduce the probability of entry. The only case in which the incumbent does not limit price is when the demand functions differ only by a constant because in this case the incumbent cannot affect the informativeness of the price level. The lemma also characterizes what limit pricing looks like. In particular, if the incumbent can reduce the probability of entry by concealing information from the entrant dG(Q1) [i.e. ('g'i-£v)_7Q__20], the incumbent limit prices by decreasing information; If I enhancing the entrant’s knowledge of demand reduces the probability of entry dG(Q,) [i.e. (Eng—s O], the incumbent limit prices by increasing the entrant’s dQ: information. Of cases a through d of Lemma 1.3, case a is the traditional result of the limit pricing literature. That is, in case a the incumbent limit prices by increasing quantity, which conceals information from the entrant. Unlike the previous literature however, this implies that the incumbent’s information is reduced as well. In case b the incumbent limit prices by reducing quantity, but also by concealing information. Harrington’s (1986) result could be adapted to fit this case. For Harrington, if the entrant and the incumbent’s costs are sufficiently correlated, higher quantities might reveal good news to the entrant, namely that it is likely to be the low cost type. The incumbent wants to limit price by setting a lower quantity and thus concealing this information from the entrant. Once again, unlike Harrington’s result, reducing the entrant’s information also reduces the incumbent’s. 31 More surprisingly however is the result that limit pricing can mean revealing information, cases c and d. Since the incumbent uses information as a strategic tool, and since more information can mean bad news to the entrant with more precise beliefs, limit pricing can very well mean enhancing the entrant’s knowledge of demand. The example of section 1.5 corresponds to case c (Figure 1.1): increasing quantity decreases the probability of entry iciQi: -—1— < 0 , and thus by Lemma 1.3 the dQ, 120 incumbent limit prices by increasing quantity, i.e. Q,* > QfE. Since increasing quantity increases information, i.e. since (E'— g ') = —1 — (—1.5) = 0.5 > O , then the incumbent limit prices by increasing the entrant’s information about demand. The intuition of this result is as follows. At the current beliefs the entrant enters, i.e. p° =O.5 > p"‘= 0.41. By increasing output the incumbent increases the chance of bad news for the entrant, and thus the probability of entry goes down. As an example of case d, assume that the two possible demand functions are given by p = 30— Q+£ and p = 20—§Q + a (Figure 1.4). Assume that a is unifome distributed in the interval [-20,20], that 5 =1, k, =4, k,. =8, 5 =20, and p° =0.7, which yields the first period sequential equilibrium is Q“ = 10.09. In this example the minimum posterior that induces entry is p* = 0.4 , thus at prior beliefs the entrant is entering. The probability of entry is given by G(Q,) = 0.23 +.01Q, , and thus a reduction in quantity, which increases information, reduces the probability of entry. According to Lemma 1.3 then the incumbent wants to increase information to increase the chance of 32 bad news, QFE > Q“. Thus the incumbent limit prices by reducing quantity, which increases information. 30 20 30 Q Figure 1.4. Expected Demand Functions: Case ((1) 1 .7 Conclusions Going back to the idea first proposed by Bain (1949) that prices embody information about the industry I study limit pricing under a set up in which prices clearly embody statistical information about the demand function. F inns do not know the demand function and learn about it through the actions of an incumbent firm that can increase or reduce the informational content of the price level to limit price. The incumbent’s costs are fully known and so its actions only reveal information about the market, both to itself and to others observing the market and contemplating 33 entry, which implies that if it wants to learn, its rival learns as well; if it wants its rival to learn less, it learns less itself. I find that in equilibrium unless the demand functions differ by a constant the incumbent firm limit prices. More importantly however is the result that limit pricing can mean revealing information to the entrant. In particular, if given current beliefs the entrant is entering the market, more information might reveal some bad news with more precise beliefs and thus reduce the probability of entry. In this case the incumbent limit prices by increasing information. It would be interesting to study the incentives to limit price in the presence of symmetric information, such as in this model, but uncertainty about different things, such as the cost functions of firms, or a general industry parameter. I would expect the results to hold: even if information is symmetric, the incumbent can manipulate the probability of good or bad news to try to deter entry. I would expect the results to also hold in a model of information jamming such as Fudenberg and Tiroles’s (1986). That is, if the entrant cannot observe the first period quantity, only the price, then it is said that the incumbent limit prices by jamming its rival’s information. Assuming that the entrant cannot observe quantity implies that the entrant and the incumbent update beliefs in a different manner and thus learn differently. The intuition behind the results should not change however. That is, even if the firms learn in different ways, the incumbent has incentives to jam the entrant’s learning so as to make entry appear less profitable. Allowing for different initial priors (asymmetric information) should also extend the results of this model, although once again, the intuition behind the results should not 34 change. That is, even if firms have different information to start with, as long as both the incumbent and the entrant are not fully informed about demand, the incumbent still has incentives to manipulate (or jam) the entrant’s learning so as to make entry appear less profitable. 35 CHAPTER 2 UNCERTAINTY, LEARNING, AND SEIGNORAGE MAXIMIZING GOVERNMENTS 2.1 Introduction The relationship between the instruments of monetary policy such as the money growth rate or the interest rate, and policy targets such as the inflation rate is not fully certain. Governments or central bankers must then conduct monetary policy less than the fully informed. To aid themselves, policy makers gather data, run econometric models, and simulate responses of the economy to various policy shocks. Moreover, they update these models regularly after new data becomes available, which means that they are trying to learn or to update their beliefs about the economic environment. This is a simultaneous control and estimation problem that affects the optimal decisions of policy makers. The policy maker tries to reach its target as best as possible given its current beliefs, but it must also revise its understanding about the relationship between instruments and targets, and as it revises its beliefs it must adjust monetary policy accordingly. The relevance of learning in monetary economics has already been recognized in the literature. Most papers however study the role of the private sector’s learning about the economic environment, but there are not many papers that study the complementary problem of learning by the monetary authority. I review the literature of learning by monetary policy makers in Section 2.2 of this essay. 36 The policy maker’s need to learn about the economy is particularly important during abnormal periods of time during which the government is very uncertain about the reaction of the economy to different monetary actions. One such period of time is a hyperinflation, or a high inflation episode. During episodes of high inflation the velocity of money increases significantly, and eventually people substitute bad (inflating) money for good, stable money (such as the dollar for example), or they simply turn to barter. In order for the government to meet its targets it must learn quickly how the demand for money will react to monetary policy. For example, if a significant portion of the government’s finances must come from seignorage, knowing to what extent people will actually use the national currency determines which portion of money issue will translate into inflation and which portion into real seignorage revenues. This in turn determines how much money the government should issue. In this paper I study the impact of learning by the monetary authorities on the optimal supply of money and the income from seignorage in one of these highly inflationary economies. I assume that the government relies heavily on money issue to finance its budget and thus its objective is to maximize seignorage. The reason why a government comes to rely largely on income from money issue can be explained using Sargent and Wallace’s (1981) unpleasant monetarist arithmetic scenario. They showed that if fiscal policy precedes monetary policy, if there is a limit to the debt that the government can issue, and if the government cannot raise taxes, then the tighter monetary policy is today, the looser it will be in the future. If the government accumulates a lot of debt and if tax collections are not significant sources of income then the government will have to issue a lot of money. 37 The conditions that lead a government to accumulate debt and to run large deficits can be as varied as the financing of a war or the inefficiency of the tax system. Deficits can soar for example during periods of civil unrest during which the government’s expenditure rises to combat the rebellious groups. Tax revenues also fall as this portion of the population stops paying taxesll . Moreover, wars in general (not only civil wars) are very difficult to finance with traditional taxes. Hamilton (1977) for example points to “the unwillingness of our political leaders in both parties to attempt to pay the cost of the (Vietnam) war through taxation”12 as the cause of the US. inflation of the 1970’s. He argues that “this method of payment would have revealed the true cost, and thus ended the war.”13 Low reliance on tax income is not exclusive to wars or social unrest. Inefficient or unsophisticated tax systems, very common in countries with high political instability and polarization, or in countries with large rural areas and poor infrastructure, result in too little resources invested in tax collection or in tax avoidance and thus in little tax revenue”. Low credit ratings and high transitory spending also increase the need for seignorage”. Transitory spending is not usually financed with tax reforms, which are meant to be permanent, but with domestic or foreign debt. If the government cannot get any loans, it turns to printing money. " Capie (1986). ‘2 Hamilton (1977), p. 17-18. '3 Hamilton (1977), p. 17-18. “ Cukierman et. al (1992). ‘5 Click (1993). 38 Finally, the inability to reach a policy decision can also lead to deteriorating deficits and to seignorage as the major temporary source of income16 . As an example consider France during the first half of the 1920’s. France needed to pay for the reparations of the war, and it was clear that the Germans could not keep up with the reparation payments imposed by the Versailles treaty. The French tried invading the region of the Ruhr in Germany to collect their production as payment but the German government promoted a policy of passive resistance during which German workers were paid not to work”. The French effort proved unsuccessful and did not solve (nor help) the budget’s problem. A tax reform was imminent but the Chamber of Deputies could not reach an agreement for several years because of the opposition between Conservatives and Socialists. This led to an 18-month period of complete fiscal inaction during which the government relied on printing money to finance itself”. All of the conditions that are likely to lead to the maximization of seignorage by the government are in essence short-lived or transitory. For this reason I work with a short horizon. In particular, I work with a two-period model. In the first period the government chooses a growth rate of money given some prior beliefs about the demand function. There are stochastic shocks to demand, a demand for money is realized, and the government collects S1 in seignorage; the government then updates its beliefs according to Bayes rule and sets a new growth of the money supply for the second period, and collects S; in seignorage. A riskier distribution of posterior beliefs in the Rothschild- 16Alesina and Drazen (1991). '7 A policy such as this also increases the government’s need for seignorage. In particular, the German policy of passive resistance and the reparation payments imposed on Germany after the war are considered to be the two leading causes of the German hyperinflation of the 1922-1923. 1’ Alesina and Drazen (1991) suggest France and other European countries as examples of this type of war of attrition where the different political parties that made up the government could not agree on fiscal reforms following the war. 39 Stiglitz sense means that the government learns or that information increases. Intuitively, a riskier distribution of beliefs makes the possible demand functions easier to distinguish. The description of this model and the definition of the equilibrium are presented in Section 2.3. In Sections 2.4 and 2.5 I present the three results from the model. I find that the government can increase real seignorage collections by learning about the demand for money (Proposition 2.1). Hence information is valuable. Intuitively, learning about the demand for money allows the government to make more accurate and efficient decisions. Given that the government gains from learning, the government actively seeks to learn (Proposition 2.2), and thus constant money growth rates are not optimal, except when the possible demand functions differ by a constant because in this case every quantity of money demanded is equally informative. Finally, for some parameter values the government induces a hyperinflation in order to learn about the demand for money (Proposition 2.3). That is, for some parameter values, if the government does not update beliefs the seignorage maximizing money growth rate is not hyperinflationary, but if the government updates beliefs the money growth rate generates a hyperinflation. If this is the case then the hyperinflation is the result of a rational decision by the government, which is interesting because as most people would agree hyperinflations should (if possible) be avoided. I should note however that this is not the result of monetary conditions but instead of fiscal policy, which determines the conduct of monetary policy. In Section 2.6 I illustrate the model and the three results with an example. I show how learning can more than triple the inflation rate and trigger a hyperinflation. 40 In Section 2.7 I present an intuitive explanation of our model, and in Section 2.8, a short case study for the Bolivian hyperinflation of the 1980’s. At last I conclude. 2.2 Literature Review In this section I review how the policy maker’s uncertainty and learning affect certain monetary problems as studied previously in other papers. The idea about learning and monetary policy goes back to the 1960’s: Brainard (1967) studied the making of monetary policy when there is uncertainty about the effect of the policy on the targets, and Poole (1970) studied the choice of policy tool under uncertainty about output. Neither one of them however studied learning. The more recent literature focus on the effects of the monetary authority’s and the public’s ability to reduce their uncertainty about the economy, e.g. Sack (1999), Kasa (1999), Hardy (1997), Caplin and Leahy (1996), Balvers and Cosimano (1994) and Bertocchi and Spagat (1993) among many others”. Bertocchi and Spagat (1993) consider a central bank that wants to minimize output variability in an infinite horizon with unknown structure of the economy. They find that Friedman’s argument (1968) for a fixed money supply rule is only optimal in very specific circumstances, because learning is valuable, and it implies periodic adjustments of the optimal monetary actions. Balvers and Cosimano (1994) study the debate of gradualism in monetary policy when the central bank minimizes the variability of inflation and is uncertain about the '9 Learning in monetary economics has concentrated mostly on learning by the public, not by the government, unlike my paper. The papers by Marcet and Nicollini (1998) and Marcet and Sargent (1987) are for example two papers that study the dynamics of hyperinflations given different learning mechanisms by the public, for example least squares learning. 41 parameters of the aggregate demand function. By assuming that inflation changes stochastically with money growth, they develop an optimal way to learn about the inflation process and find that gradual convergence of money growth is optimal, because, although sharp reductions in money growth increase information about the economy, they also increase its variability, which makes it harder to forecast future inflation. Caplin and Leahy (1996) study a central bank that learns via the reactions of the investors in a recession to the choice of monetary policy. They find that very gradual reductions in interest rates are ineffectual whereas aggressive polices are more successful, because when faced by small cuts in interest rates investors have new information that implies that further cuts may be in order and thus wait to invest. Aggressive policies on the other hand, reveal that there will probably be no further cuts and induce higher investment. Hardy (1997), by studying how different central banks intervene in different ways in the financial market to keep interest rates near their targets, argues that the design of instruments has an important effect on the informational content of market prices. Since information is valuable in the determination of the operational target, by not intervening the central bank allows fluctuations that give rise to valuable information. One implication of Hardy’s result is that since information increases the value function of the central bank, monetary policy actually reduces market efficiency. Kasa (1999) considers a central bank that attempts to stabilize output and inflation but is unsure about the relationship between these two variables. He derives conditions on parameter values that lead the central bank to erroneously believe that there is an 42 exploitable relation between output and inflation, which provides a new explanation to the inflation bias. Finally, Sack (1999) sets up a model of monopoly experimentation when the Federal Reserve sets an interest rate rule, is uncertain about the policy multiplier and learns through the reaction of the economy to monetary policy. He finds that since the Fed faces greater uncertainty about the impact of its policy as it moves away from the previous interest rate level, the optimal monetary rule is gradual adjustments towards the target. The previous papers have in common that they study a central bank seeking to maximize a social benefit over an infinite time horizon, whether it is a trade off between output and inflation, the minimization of inflation variability, maximization of output, etc, and they do it in the presence of uncertainty and learning. In my paper however, as a result of fiscal policy the government needs to maximize seignorage. Since this is likely a short term objective, I restrict my analysis to a short horizon. This model can be used to determine the conditions (as in Bertocchi and Spagat (1993)) under which Friedman’s argument is true in a scenario in which the government needs to finance itself strictly with money creation, but can also be used to determine what learning does to money growth and to seignorage, and the conditions under which learning leads to hyperinflations, which has not been studied before. 43 2.3 Model and Equilibrium 2.3.1 The Basic Model There are two periods. At time t=1 the state of the economy is as follows: the government has a high level of desired spending, past inflation is high, people are not buying bonds and the government cannot raise taxes, and thus to finance public expenditures it must issue money. Given the stock of high—powered money, the government selects a growth rate for the money supply for the period, gl , and collects seignorage, 5,. Seignorage in period t is given by the rate of growth of money times the supply of real balances, where M, is the nominal supply of money, 13 is the price level, and g, is the growth rate of money supply in period t. The condition for equilibrimn in the money market is given by, M —J'=L(ir!),r)r ! where L(i Y) is the demand for real balances, i is the nominal interest rate and Y, is (’1 real output. Assume a traditional money demand function, i.e. dL(11,__,_Y ’) < 0 and I! > 0. Also assume that the interest rate and the output level are functions of the __(__dLil. Y) dY I money growth rate. According to Fisher’s theorem (1930), the nominal interest rate can be written as follows, (1+1}) = (1+r.)(1+flf), where r , is the real rate and 723‘ are the expectations of inflation, and where both 7; and Irf are functions of g,. Thus the reduced form equation for the interest rate can be written as, i, =a+flg, (2-1) or is a positive parameter, and ,Bcan be positive or negative. If an increase in the money growth rate reduces the interest rate, which is known as the liquidity effect, then ,6 < 0, otherwise, 13> 0. The traditional explanation given to the liquidity effect is that without flexible prices, an increase in money growth requires a reduction in real rates. (Think of the IS- LM model. An increase in money growth shifts the LM curve to the right along the downward sloping IS curve.) Additionally, an increase in money growth increases inflation expectations. If the reduction in the real rate more than offsets the increase in expectations, we say that we have the liquidity effect. In highly inflationary economies I would expect the effect of expectations of inflation to dominate over the interest rate effect, and thus that ,6 > 0. Output is also a fimction of money growth, Y. = i’ + 45g, (22) where 1" is the (known) level of output associated with full employment. 45 If an increase in the money growth rate increases output (i.e. (i > 0), I have the Tobin effect; if it reduces output (i.e. ¢ < 0), the anti-Tobin effect. The Tobin effect is the effect that an increase in the rate of growth of money supply has on the demand for assets. If there is a Tobin effect, an increase in the rate of growth of money, which increases the cost of holding cash balances decreases the demand for real balances; individuals switch out of money and into equities, which increases the demand for capital and thus increases output. Increasing the money growth rate also reduces the demand for bank deposits, which means that bank lending is reduced to firms that want to purchase capital goods. The anti-Tobin effect results is the reduction in investment fi'om firms dominates over the individuals’ increased demand for assets”. In highly inflationary economies the effect of money growth on the real variables is expected to be small compared to the nominal changes in the economy and thus that ¢z0. Let m, = ' , then, based on equations (2.1) and (2.2) assume that the money 5|: demand equation can be written as a function of the rate of growth of money as follows”, m, = l(g,,Q)+£, (2.3) where a, is a random shock to demand, distributed with a continuous, differentiable distribution function f (8,) in — oo < s < oo , and with zero expectation. The shock a, is 2° Gale (1983), pages 8-9. 2' An extension of this model is to consider heteroskedastic shocks as follows, m, = l (g, ,Q) + g,s, . 46 meant to capture all the variables excluded from the analysis, as well as the stochastic nature of the economyzz. Q is a set of parameters unknown to the govermnent, which include among others a,,6 and ¢. l(g,,Q) is a function of the rate of growth of money such that £54m=ltgnfn s O and l(g,,Q)+g,l'(g,,Q) is strictly decreasing in g,. That is, g, assume that the demand function is downward sloping”, and that marginal revenue from seignorage is decreasing. The latter assumption is satisfied for example if l(g,,Q) is concave or not too convex. The reason why I want to introduce the latter assumption about the demand for money (that l(g,,Q)+g,l'(g,,Q) is decreasing in g,) is that I want to have a Laffer- curve such as in Figure 2.1, as I explain next. Remember that seignorage is given by the demand for real balances times the rate of growth of money, S, = g,l(g,,Q). Since demand is downward sloping, as g, increases, l(g,,Q) decreases, and hence the two terms in the seignorage equation move in opposite directions, i.e. dS T'=I(g.,n)+g.1'(g,.n). g I 22 Since the distribution of a is independent of g, and since I assume that -00 < s < co , my formulation allows the possibility that m<0. This assumption significantly simplifies the analysis, and it is traditionally used in the learning literature given the transparency of the results. When dealing with examples 1 will however assume that negative quantities are not allowed. 23 It is in principle possible to obtain positively sloped demand functions by assuming a Tobin effect and a liquidity effect. This possibility however does not appear to be very attractive, specially during hyperinflations when one would expect the effect of expectations of inflation to be large compared to changes in the real side of the economy. 47 where the first term is positive, and the second term is negative. As g, approaches zero g, l '(g,,Q) approaches zero (as long as l '(g,,Q) does not go to minus infinity too fast). Since I(g,,Q) is positive, then for low values of g, increasing the rate of growth of money increases seignorage. However, it is reasonable to assume that as g, becomes very large, the second effect dominates the first. This means that it is reasonable to assume that the seignorage function is concave in g, , or that demand function is such that l(g,,Q) + g,l '(g, ,Q) is decreasing in g,. ’g Figure 2.1. Seignorage Function with Laffer Curve Property There are several possible representations for the money demand function, e. g. Cagan’s (1956), Blanchard and Fischer’s ( 1993), and Lucas’ (1994). Cagan (1956) suggested that a good representation for the demand for money _ a—bi,+lnY, during hyperinflations is given by m — e hence, I 9 48 -b’,lnY,_ -b-b,li, -» I(g,,§2)=e" '+ —e" a ”g +"‘ i“ ’ , where a and b are posrtlve parameters. Cagan’s formulation is usually used for convenience, although it appears to resemble high inflation economies very well. Blanchard and Fischer (1993 — p. 513-517) suggest a more general demand function for money of the form =0(r;+7rf), where 6'(-)<024. In this case, .~< [_5 l(g,,Q) = 6(7; +7t,‘)Y,. Another representation of the demand for money (although not necessarily a good fit for a hyperinflation) is given by l(g,,Q) = Ai’”Y , where A is a constant, and where both the nominal interest rate and real income can be functions of the money growth rate. This function is used by Lucas (1994) to characterize the US. data”. Under either Cagan’s (1956) or Blanchard and Fischer’s (1993) specifications, Y and r are assumed to be constant. The argument traditionally given is that during hyperinflations the changes in the real variables in the economy are either null or very small compared to the large changes in money supply and prices. A notable exception to this hypothesis has been suggested by Pickersgill (1968) for the hyperinflationary episode in the Soviet Union during 1921-1926. I will not follow any particular form for the demand for money, but instead work with the general specification l(g,,Q). e “"bmflq ) and i, = r, + nf , Blanchard and Fisher’s specification becomes 2‘ If for example 90‘, +7rf) = e Cagan’s. 2’ Of the three demand functions reviewed only Lucas’ specification satisfies the restrictions of this model, given some additional restrictions on the signs of ,6 and d. 49 To introduce uncertainty, assume that the demand function can take on one of the two following representations, m, =1(g,,§)+a, , (2.4) m, = l(g,,Q)+e, , (2.5) and assume that Vg, I(g,,§) 21(g,,Q_). This means that one demand function is always above the other, and thus I will refer to l(g,,-O) as the “high” demand curve and to l(g,,_g) as the “low” demand curve. I explain the meaning of this assumption in a later section. In the first period, the govermnent has a prior belief p, that the demand for money is equation (2.4), i.e. it believes that the correct parameters are T)- with prior probability ,a, , and with prior probability 1- u, that they are _Q. In period one, the government chooses a growth rate for the money supply g,(,u,) , and a value of e and hence ml are realized. The government’s expected seignorage in period one is then, EMS: =[fll1(g.,5)+(1-#1)1(g.,9)]gl- The government does not observe the realization of a, but a, prevents the government from perfectly learning the parameters of the demand function after the first period. The observation of ml , together with knowledge of g,(p,) , leads the government to revise its beliefs about 0. Let p, be the posterior belief that the correct parameters are 5 , then, through Bayes rule write ,u, as follows, 50 Am. —I(g. ,5» ”’ = (1-#1)f(ml —1(gpQ))+Mf(ml-l(gle5)) ' With the new beliefs, the government sets a growth rate of money for the second period, g2 (,a,)and collects S2012) in seignorage. 2.3.2 The Equilibrium Since posterior beliefs are a function of prior beliefs and of the first period money growth rate, I solve for the second period equilibrium first. In period 2, the government maximizes expected seignorage given posterior beliefs, E..Sz =[#21(g2a§)+(1—#2)1(g2e9)]82, with respect to g2 . The first order condition is given by, [AItg.,fi)+(1—A)I(g.._a)]+[lhIrefi)+(1-h211'rg.,a)]g. =0, and the second order condition by, 2[#21'(gze6)+(1-.U2)1'(82eQ)]+[#2("(g2,§)+(1-#2)1'(82e@]82 so. Let g2 (11,) denote the second period optimal money grth rate. Given the assumptions about l(g,,Q) , the second order condition is satisfied with strict inequality, and thus g2 (#2) denotes a unique maximum. Let S2 "' ([1,) denote the resulting value function of the government, that is, S. *(112)=[#21(g2(,u2),6)+(1-#2)l(g2(#2),Q)]g2(/12). In the first period the government chooses a rate of growth of money by maximizing expected seignorage over the two periods. Since in period one the posterior 51 beliefs #2 are a random variable whose distribution function depends upon the first period money growth rate and upon the distribution of ml implied by a, I take the expectation of the second period seignorage over all possible beliefs and all possible amounts of money demanded. Assuming that the time discount parameter is given by 6 , the government’s first period problem is as follows, Max EMS, + a j 52 *(p,)h(m,g)dm, 81 where the distribution m implied by e is given by, h(m.g) = (1— #1 )f(m —I(g.a» + #lf(m — I(g,§)). Let gl (a) be the equilibrium money growth rate in period one. 2.3.3 The Myopic Equilibrium In this dynamic problem periods one and two are connected by posterior beliefs. Thus when the government chooses gl (,u,) it accounts for the effect of period one money growth on posterior beliefs, and of posterior beliefs on second period seignorage. I now want to compare gl (p,) with the money growth rate that the government would set if it did not account for the effect of g,(,u,) on posterior beliefs. Therefore, I compare g,(,u,) with the optimal myopic money growth rate, gmp,c(p,), which is chosen to maximize first period expected seignorage, Max E A Sl . 81 (Note that gmpkml) and g,(p,) only differ in the value of ,u. The first and second order conditions are also the same except for the value of p .) 52 If the government issues a rate g,(,u,) different than the myopic rate gmpkful), then the government experiments; if this leads to a riskier distribution of beliefs, then it increases information. 2.4 The Value of Information In the previous section I defined the equilibrium money growth rate g,(,u,) and the myopic money growth rate gmp,c(p,) , and defined the difference between the two as the amount of experimentation. Thus experimentation is the deviation from myopic policies in order to increase or reduce information, where more information means a riskier distribution of posterior beliefs. In this section I study whether the government benefits from more information. Blackwell (1951, 1953) defined more informative experiments and the sufficient conditions for a more informative experiment to be valuable. Intuitively, an experiment 2; is more informative than an experiment 22, if every distribution of beliefs that can be generated from 22, can also be generated by z]. Formally, an experiment is a pair of measures [f (m—l(g, Q», f (m—l(g,§))], one for each state of nature that gives the distribution of the first period money demand. Definition: An experiment 21 = [ f (m—1(g ", Q», f (m—l(g ",O))] is more informative than an experiment 22 = [f (m — l(g ', 9)), f (m - l(g ', 5))1 , if Izdg 2 jZ(#2(g'lm))h(meg)dm for every continuous, convex function x(,u,(g",m)) : [0,1] —> ‘R . 53 In the spirit of Blackwell (1951, 1953), the second derivative of the second period 2 :1- value function with respect to beliefs, %, is called the value of information, and more information is said to be good if the second period value function is convex in beliefs, which comes from the definition of a more informative experiment. In my model, experiments are rates of growth of the money supply, observations are money demanded, and more informative experiments are determined by the demand functions as follows. Remember that Vg, , l(g,,§)21(g,,g), which implies that the two demand functions look like one of the two panels in Figure 2.2 (although they do not have to be straight lines). In Figure 2.2(a) the possible distribution functions of ml implied by gl move further apart and overlap less as gl increases. Thus a greater gl produces a more informative signal. On panel (b), the possible distributions of MI move closer together and overlap more as gl increases, and thus a greater g1 produces a less informative signal. Intuitively, more informative money growth rates spread the means of the two possible demand functions apart making them more distinguishable. Proposition 2.1: The government that maximizes expected seignorage values 2 a1: __dsz 91»... information, i.e. dflz Proof: See Appendix B. 54 , \ 4g , , g (a) (b) Figure 2.2. Informativeness of the Inflation Rate Proposition 2.1 shows that the government values more information. Mathematically, since expected seignorage is a linear function of posterior beliefs, the value function is the supremum of a collection of linear firnctions, and it is thus convex. Intuitively, more information is valuable because it allows the government to make a better informed decision. 2.5 Effects of Experimentation in High Inflation Economies In this section I study the government’s incentives, created by the effect of period one money growth rates on the informativeness of money demanded, for the government to adjust the rate of growth of money supply away from the myopically optimal rates. To do so, I compare the first order conditions of the myopic and non-myopic problems. 55 The non-myopic government maximizes 5.1.51 + 6 IS, "‘(p2 )h(m,g)dm , and the myopic government, E ”I Sl , both with respect to g,. Therefore, if d I S. *(#2)h(m,g)dm "° d > (<)0, in order for the non-myopic first order condition to be 31 dE S satisfied, d” l < (>)0. This means that the myopic objective function is decreasing 81 (increasing) at g, (a). Since expected seignorage is a concave function, it is decreasing (increasing) only for values of gl above (below) gmp,c(,u,). Graphically this argument is represented in Figure 2.3. dEp, S1 (#1) < O dg 1 Ep. S1 (#1) 4 W gmpicUJl) 31011) Figure 2.3. Conditions under which the Non-Myopic Inflation Rate is Higher than the Myopic Rate 56 d I S. *(flz)h(m,g)dm After some algebra (in Appendix B) ‘°° d can be written as a 31 function of the value of information and of the amount of information. In particular, d IS. *(;12)h(m,g)dm dgl (125,1- all 1— 2 d .2.6 an? M “)dm£m( ) =(I'(g..5)—I'(g..e» I The relation l'(g,,§) > (<)l'(g,,@ indicates whether increasing the money growth rate increases (decreases) information. In Figure 2.2(a) l'(g,,E2-) >l'(g,,_g), hence, increasing the rate of growth of money spreads the means of the two demand functions apart so that they become more distinguishable. Higher money growth rates are thus more informative. Since information is valuable (Proposition 2.1), one would expect the government to increase the rate of growth of money above the myopic rate to increase information. Alternatively, if l'(g,,5) l'(g.,el. Proof: See section Appendix B. The relation between the myopic money growth rate gm”, (,u,) , the non-myOpic money growth rate gl ([1,) , and the second period money growth rate g2 (#2), is presented in Figure 2.4. In the graph, by assumption, there are three possible posterior beliefs, ,u, > p, , ,u, = ,u, and p2 < ,u,. Figure 2.4(a) represents the three possible time paths for the growth rate of money when l'(g,,O) 21'(g,,Q) . For presentation purposes I assume that before period one the prevailing rate of growth is the myopic rate. In period one, the growth rate jumps up to g,(,u,) , because this increases information. In period two it can go either up or down again depending on posterior beliefs. For example, if the posterior beliefs are the same as the prior beliefs, the second period money growth rate is exactly the same myopic rate, i.e. g2 (,uI ) = gmp,c(p,) . Figure 2.4(b) shows the possible paths when l'(g,,§)sl'(g,,Q), which corresponds to Figure 2.2(b). In period one the rate is lower than the myopic rate because 58 this increases information, but in period two it can go up or down depending on posterior beliefs. 8 g A #2 >141 I g I 112 >111 gmyopic H2 :11] gmyopic P2 :11] 112 1 2 t 1 2 t I'(g..fi)21'(g..s_2) I'tg..'6)s1'(g..a) (a) (b) Figure 2.4: Money Growth Paths Finally, I can identify the conditions under which experimentation leads to a hyperinflation, which I present formally in proposition 2.3. The definition of a hyperinflation is arbitrary. Cagan, for example, who was the first to study hyperinflations, defined a hyperinflationary episode as starting in the month the inflation rate is above 50% and ending in the month when it has fallen below that rate and has stayed there for at least a year. His definition is arbitrary, but it served the purpose of his study of seven hyperinflations of the 1920’s and 1940’s. Other definitions are slacker, or cover longer periods of time. I will not specify a particular inflation rate as 59 hyperinflationary, thus when I say that the money growth rate is hyperinflationary, I mean that it leads to a very high inflation rate. Definition: The money growth rate gl is hyperinflationary if it leads to an inflation rate above I, where the inflation rate is given by, ”(gl)=(-——R§,g') ~1], and the price level is given by, (1+g,)M0 . l(gl!Q)+£l Pl (gt) = To obtain a hyperinflation as the result of experimentation, the myopic rate must not be hyperinflationary (i.e. it must lead to yearly inflation rates below I or below 8,000% if we were to follow Cagan’s definition), but the optimal amount of experimentation must be large enough to generate a hyperinflation. This case is represented in Figure 2.5 and in Proposition 2.3. To establish Proposition 2.3 I compare the myopic and nonmyopic problems for the cases where higher money growth rates are more informative“. I assume that gm”, (,u,) is not conducive to a hyperinflation but that gl (#1) is, and I look at the conditions that make the difference between these two rates, which is given by equation (2.6), large (hyperinflationary). 2‘ I could apply Proposition 2.3 to hyperdeflations. In this case I would study cases where decreasing the money growth rate increases information, such as Figure (2b). 60 git T—L_ > Hyperinflationary gmyopic Figure 2.5. Hyperinflationary Money Growth Paths Proposition 2.3: Assume that the myopic inflation rate is not hyperinflationary, i.e. _ <1+g....,..(h.»Mo _ _ _ MW“’[Itgm...(hi.m+el 1]" "’ where n E R4, , and where R, is normalized to one. Then if the following two conditions are true, hyperinflations are the optimal result of uncertainty and learning: (3.1) Increasing the rate of growth of money increases information, i.e. I'(g..fi)>1'(g.,t2), and 61 (l(gmp,c,Q) + 6,)n * d” [12 l-u, — £17712 2 ( )dm 1" M0 (3.2) 6(I'rg.,5)—I'(g.,a» I :52 ,u Proof: Since I '(g,,(_2) > I '(g,,Q) then the non-myopic inflation rate is above the myopic rate (Proposition 2.2), and thus given that l'(gl , Q) < 0 , then, [ (1+gm...(a»Mo H (Harrow. J l(gmyopic ([1,),0) + £1 — l(g1(/11):Q) + £1 and thus ”(Sample (#1)) 5 ”(gr (#1)) - Condition 3.2 is a sufficient condition for the difference between these two rates to be larger than n, that is, (1+ g1 (.111 ))Mo _ (1+ gmyopic(/11))MO «graham. Ilg....-.(A).n)+e' ”(81011))" ”(gmpic (.ul )) = Note that since I '(gl ,9) < 0 and gm”, (11,) s g1 (11,) , then, (1+gl(/«))Mo 2 (1+gl(#l))Mo l(gl(/1l)an)+gl l(gmyopic(/11)9Q)+£l, and thus that, (1+g. (#1))M0 _ (1+gm...(M))Mo (gm... (#1), 9) +6. “gm-4710.0) + a. ' 7r(gl(rul))-”(gmyopic(#l)) 2] Hence, if (1+gl(M))M0 _ (1+gmyopic(#l))MO > l(gnryopic(#l)ra)+£l l(gnryopic(lul)’Q)+£l- 9 which is equivalent to, (l(gnryopic (#1 ), Q) + 51)” Mo (g. (#1 ) - awn-4711)) 2 9 62 then Mg. (h. )1 — hummus) 2 n, and thus Mg. (#1 » 2 1. Now note that the non-myopic inflation rate equals the myopic inflation rate plus the optimal amount of experimentation, where the latter is given by equation 2.6 (see proof in Appendix B), thus, d S "‘ d 2 #2(1-.U1) ”21m. _ 6° 2 g.(u)—g...,..(h.)=S(I'(g..Q)—I'(g..a» I d”, dm Thus, if (l(gmyopic’a) + £1)" — "’sz * dp, 61' ,Q -I' ,Q ———2— 1— -— d 2 ((g. ) (gl_)) I M“ h.) dmi’" M. then ate. (#1 )1 2 I. For experimentation to lead to hyperinflations I need that higher money growth rates be more informative, and that the incentives to experiment (equation (2.6)) be large. Among other things, the larger the discount parameter 5 , the larger the value of 2 :1: information d S’, , and the more spread out the demand functions, that is the larger #2 l '(g,,5) - l '(g,,Q) , the larger the amount of experimentation. In particular, the more spread apart the means of the two possible distribution functions of posterior beliefs, the more there is to be learned, and thus the more likely is the government to hyperinflate. That is, the probability that the non-myopic money growth rate is hyperinflationary equals the following probability, 63 sz * d 2. lea—h.) ”2 1d»: dp, dm -l(gmyopic9n) 9 Moatl'rg..fi)—I'(g..a» I n Pr 3,5 2S2; 2 which given 20, increases as l'(g,,§—2)—l'(g,,Q) increases. Thus, the larger l'(gl ,5) — l'(gl , Q) , the larger the probability that learning leads to a hyperinflation. In Figure 2.6(b) for example, I '(g,,§)- I'(g,,_Q) is larger than in Figure 2.6(a), thus a hyperinflation is more likely under Figure 2.6(b) than under Figure 2.6(a). (a) (b) Figure 2.6. Spread of the Possible Demand Functions I should emphasize that although in this model the introduction of learning can lead to large (hyperinflationary) money growth rates, this is the result of fiscal decisions which precede monetary policy and which determine the need for large seignorage. 64 2.6 Solution for Uniformly Distributed Shocks and Linear Demand Functions To illustrate the results from the model I solve for the simplest possible case, linear demand functions and uniformly distributed random shocks. This example is meant to illustrate how significant the effect of learning can be on the inflation rate and on the seignorage level, and how a rational government can induce hyperinflations to learn about demand. Assume that the random shocks 5, are distributed uniformly on the interval [-2.115,2.115]. The demand function is linear in the nominal interest rate and output level, 771, = a-bi, + Y, +8, , which using equations (2.1) and (2.2) leads to m,=(a-ba+Y)+(¢—b,6)g,+a,. That is 1(g,,O)=(a-ba+i')+(¢—bp)g, and O: {a,b,a,fi,¢,Y}. Assume that prior beliefs are given by p1=0.5, and that Z—W=—o.os, g-gg=-o.l9, and Z-Ed: g—bg+Y=9. Graphically, these types of demand functions correspond to Figure 2.2(a). Finally, assume starting values go = g......(h.) and 1% =1- 1 am assuming that (¢—b,6) < 0 for both types of demand functions. This is a sign restriction that must be imposed to satisfy the restrictions on money demand (I ' < 0 and 21'+ gl"<0). Assuming that (¢—b,6) < 0 is a reasonable assumption for highly inflationary economies where it is expected that the effect of the money growth rate on the real variables of the economy be negligible or at least small compared to the effects on the monetary variables (the expectations of inflation). It would therefore be expected that ,6 > 0 and It to be close to zero, and thus (¢ ——b,6) < 0. 65 Since 9 — 0.08g + 5 >9 — 0.19g + a Vg , then 9 — 0.0.8g + a is called the “high” demand, and 9 -0.19g +8 , the “low” demand. #0 = 0.5 is then the prior belief that the demand is the “high” one. With a uniform distribution fimction there are only three possible posterior beliefs as follows. Since 8 e[-2.115,2.115], then m, e (9—-0.l9gI -2.115,9—0.19gl +2.115) if 9—0.19gl +3 is the true demand, and ml 6 (9—0.08g, —2.115,9—0.08gI +2.115) if 9—0.08g| + e is the true demand function. If observed money demand is at least 9—0.19gl —2.1 15 but strictly less than 9—-0.08gl —2.1 15 , then only the “low” demand could have generated this observation. In this case the government learns that the true demand fimction is 9—0.19g,+£. The posterior belief is thus given by ,u2 =0. If observed money demand is between 9 —0.l9gl + 2.115 and 9—0.08gl + 2.115 , then only the “high” type of demand function could have generated the observation. The government thus learns that this is the true demand, p, =1. Otherwise, the government does not learn anything. In summary, the three possible posterior beliefs are, 0 if 9—0.19g,-2.1155m,<9—0.08g,-2.115 #2: ,u, if 9—0.08gl—2.115 sm,s9—o.l9g,+2.115. 1 if 9—0.19g,+2.115=(l—h.)f(m-I(g.n»+h.f(m—I(g.fi». Since by assumption p, =0.5, then the distribution of ml is given by h(m, g) = 0.5 f (m -I(g,@) + 0.5 f (m —l(g,§)) . Note however that from Bayes’ rule if the posterior belief is given by p, = 0 then, 0-5f(m1-I(gn§)) = 0.5f(m. -l(g.,Q))+0-5f(ml-1(g.,5)) Q 0 = O'Sflm' ”l(g"m)’ and for ,u2 =1, 0.5f(m. —I(g.,fi» : 0.5/(m1—1(gp9_))+0.5f(m, _l(g1’§)) <3 0 :05f(ml -I(gl"_2)) , thus, , f(m 3&9» if 9—.19g,—2.115$m,<9—.08g,—2.115 h(m,g)=< f(m-l(g’g):f(m"l(g’a» if 9—.08g,-2.115$m,S9—.19g,+2.115 f(m';(g’9)) if 9-.19g,+2.1150. This assumption is crucial in the 90 literature as the existence of this difference gives rise to the government’s (and the bank’s) incentives to inflate above the inflation target. Barro and Gordon (1983) and Calvo (1978) suggest that in the presence of labor market distortions such as unemployment compensation and income taxation, the natural output level will tend to be inefficiently low. Another motivation (Walsh (2000)) can be provided by the presence of a monopolistic competitive sector that leads to an equilibrium output level that is too low. If this is the case the government might pursue an output level above the natural level. The value of E is determined from the government’s fiscal side optimization problem. I will not address this problem in this paper. Instead I will assume that monetary policy is carried out given a predetermined value for E. Precommitment I first present the precomrnitment outcome, when the government is able to commit to the announced inflation rate. Since in this case welfare losses are at a minimum it serves as the benchmark case. The sequence of events in the model is as follows. First the public sets expectations Tl: ,' and based on these expectations the public sets nominal wages. Then the supply shock a, is realized. The government, who functions as CB, observes a, and sets inflation. Hence output is realized. The government sets inflation by minimizing the expected present discounted value of (3.1) subject to (3.2) and subject to the restriction that average inflation equals 91 announced inflation on average (the precommitrnent assumption). The resulting inflation rate is given by“), n'precommitment =;___8 . (33) The optimal response of inflation to a supply shock is negatively proportional to a . A negative aggregate supply shock lowers output, and to stabilize output, inflation should be increased. The more the government cares about output stabilization relative to inflation stabilization, i.e. the larger A , the larger l—k—A, and hence the larger the + adjustment in inflation. Expected losses for the government under precommitrnent are given by E(LG.Prewmmitment) = k 0,: + £332 . 2(1+ 7t) 2 It is well known that this policy is time inconsistent and therefore not credible. Once expectations are formed according to the policy rule given by (3.3) and nominal wages set, the government has incentives to deviate from (3.3) to stimulate output. 4" Given that the government acts as the bank, it knows all the variables at the time of its minimization problem. Thus it minimizes (l) with respect to it , and n,‘ , subject to the restriction that expected inflation equals announced inflation on average. 1 thus minimize the Lagrangian, %[A(1t,-1t,' +c, -})’ +(1r,-1T)2]+00[7r,' -E(n,)], with respect to it, , n,‘ and a) , where to is the Lagrangian multiplier associated with the constraint that n,‘ equal the mathematical expectation of it, , conditional on the public’s information. dE(1t,) _ l —A.(1t, -1t,' +8, —;)+0) = 0 and (iii) n,‘ -E(n,) = 0. Taking the expectation of (ii) and combining it The first order conditions are (1) Mn, -1t,' +8, —})+ (it, —1T)-to 0 , (ii) with (iii) yields a) = 4.}. Taking the expectation of (i) and combining with (D = 46 and 1t,‘ = 1? yields dig.) =,, Subs,,,u,,ng ‘%’H_)=1 and m :4} in (i) yields equation (3.3). More detailed explanations of this precommitrnent scenario can be found in Persson and Tabellini (1993). 92 Therefore it is more realistic to assume that the government is not able to precommit to an announced inflation rate. Discretion without delegation If the government is not able to bind itself to its announcements, the optimal inflation rate is found by minimizing (3.1) with respect to n, , subject to (3.2) and taking expectations of inflation as given. The first order condition of the government yields, 'scretionw o e ation A. “e +—"'8 +7? ’d' / (“98 = ( t y ) . (34) (1+7t) fl Since the public is aware that the government sets inflation according to the rule (3.4) expectations of inflation are given by, A(1tf+;—e)+1? (1+7e) TE: = E(1t:iiscretion w/odelegalion) : E[ ]:fl: = x;+;, (35) where E represents the expectation given the public’s information. Expected inflation exceeds the optimal target 1? by it; because of the incentives to create an inflation surprise in order to stimulate output. Substituting (3.5) in (3 .4) gives the discretion equilibrium inflation rate in the absence of delegation, . . . — 7t - 7t tducrehon w/odelegatlon : 1t ——8 + A 1+ k . _ precommitment — _ “II, + 1y The government sets an inflation rate above the optimal precommitrnent rate by A; in order to bring output closer to the target. 93 Expected losses of the government under discretion without delegation are E (Lo'd'“""°""” °"""g"”°”) -—L 2 $93-97, which are higher than expected losses _ O a 20 + A) 2 under precommitrnent. The government could thus try to delegate monetary policy to an independent central bank to try to reduce these losses. Delegation with discretion Assume now that monetary policy is conducted by an instrument-independent central bank, whose preferences are uncertain at the moment of delegation. Assume that the CB’s loss function is given by, cs __ 1 - 2 - 2 L. —3[0» —a) (y, —y) +(1+a)(n. —n) ]. (3.6) where or e (—l,?») is a stochastic parameter unobserved by the government and the private sector. Assume that in the first period the government and the public have some beliefs about a , such that the expected value of a is given by E (0t), and its variance by 0:. Finally, assume that or is independent of e , hence E (as) = 0 4'. Note that if at = —l , the banker is an “employment nutter” — according to Mervyn King’s (1997) jargon - a banker that only cares about output; if a = A , the bank is an " The way uncertainty is modeled in Beetsma and Jensen (1998) is referred to as “pure” uncertainty. It is called pure uncertainty because the sum of the coefficients of the banker’s function equals the sum of the coefficients of the government’s function, i.e. (A -a)+(l +ct) = 1+ 1 , which implies that the preferences of the banker on average coincide with the preferences of the government (or society), and that monetary policy will on average coincide with monetary policy in the absence of uncertainty about the banker’s preferences. A way to relax this assumption is to assume the following objective function for the banker, L,“ = a}. (y, -;)z + (l + x)(1t, —1?)2] , where x is a stochastic parameter. 94 “inflation nutter” because it only cares about inflation; if a = O the banker’s and the government’s preferences are the same. The central bank chooses inflation by minimizing the discounted value of (3.6) subject to (3.2) and taking the expectations of inflation as given, which results in an discretion inflation rate, 1t , given by, discretion _ (A. _a)(n’€ +;-8)+(1+a);t- ' (1+;t) ' 1t (3-7) Since the public is aware that inflation is set to satisfy (3.7), inflation expectations are given by, TI: =E(n’discretion)=E[(x —a)(7tf+;-8)+(l+a)7?] (HA) 2 (Mn: = (A —E(a))(n: +})+ (1+ 5(a))? . Canceling terms and rearranging yields, a: 44.93301)". (3.8) (1+E(a)) Substituting (3.8) in (3.7) gives the equilibrium inflation rate when monetary policy is delegated to the CB, nfiscretion _;_()" ’U.) + (x _a) 3; 1+)» 1+E(ct) (3.9) = n'precommitment + (A. ’a) 3; a 8 1+E(0t) 1+), 95 The term represents the distortions on the reactions to supply shocks as (1+)t (7» ~00 - relative to what is socially optimal. The term y represents the bank’s incentives to create output surprises. A negative aggregate supply shock, which lowers output, induces an increase in e , which is less than (iv-<1) + inflation to stabilize output. The CB increases inflation by — the increase that the government would like for positive values of a , and more than the government would like for negative values of or . Finally, the larger or , i.e. the less the central banker cares about output, the smaller the incentives of the CB to create output surprises. The expected losses of the government under delegation are given by, zlflflcuawmwnr)?‘ EU“ ...a....) 2(1+>.) ‘ 2(1+E(ot)) Since delegation of monetary policy to the central bank does not bring inflation down to the precommitrnent level, nor does it improve on welfare, the government can try to design contracts that give incentives to the CB to set the precommitment inflation rate. Walsh (1995) showed that as long as the government and the bank have the same preferences such a contract exists. We now study whether it also exists when the bank does not necessarily share the government’s preferences over output and inflation, and furthermore, the government is unsure about these preferences. 96 Linear contracts Assume that the government wants to design a contract to try to induce the CB to set the precommitment inflation rate. Let the new loss function of the CB be given by, L,CB+m,(1t, —1?), (3.10) where m, defines the contract: If actual inflation is above the target the banker incurs a penalty of size m, for each additional unit of inflation above the target. The purpose of the contract is to increase the marginal cost of inflation of the banker (by m, ). The government therefore wants to artificially generate conservative central bankers (such as Rogoff’s) without inducing distortions in the reactions to supply shocks (if possible). Note that the contract is not meant to reflect the preferences of the government over inflation stabilization. That is, the government dislikes inflation above or below 1? , but bankers are not punished for setting inflation below 1? . The purpose of the contract is to increase the banker’s marginal cost of inflation to induce lower inflation rates (if . . . . . - I. pOSSlble to induce the precomrmtment lnflatlon rate, 1: —fi8 )42. + In order to set the contract m, the government forecasts the bank’s reaction function. The central bank minimizes the discounted expected value of (3.10) subject to (3.2) with respect to 1!, , and taking the expectations of inflation as given, which is ‘2 This issue also arises when contracts are defined as is traditionally done in the literature, as "1,1: , . In this case, bankers are punished by setting any positive inflation rate, even the socially desirable inflation rate 1: , or the precommitment inflation rate. The relevant point however is that the marginal cost of inflation also increases by m,. Furthermore, if the bankers and the government have the same preferences, then the government can manipulate the banker’s marginal cost of inflation, inducing the precommitrnent inflation rate without inducing distortions in the stabilization of supply shocks (Walsh (1995)). 97 equivalent to solving a sequence of single period decision problems”. The first order condition of this problem is given by, (it—0t)(1t,—1t,‘+8,-;)+(1+0t)(1t,-1-t-)+m, =0. Collecting 1t, , n _(x—ot)(n;—e,+"y‘)+(l+ot)it'—m, " (1+7.) ' The public is aware of CB’s reaction function and thus the expectations of inflation are given by, n, =E[(x -a)(1tf-8,+;)+(l+0t)1-t——m,]. (1+)t) Since the expected value of and as, is zero, n. = (x -E(a»(n: +})+(1+E(a»v?—m. ' 0+2.) ' Solving for 1t,‘ , , - A—E(a)- 1 =1r+ y— m,. 1+E(0t) 1+E(a) Plugging 1r f in the CB’s reaction firnction yields the CB’s inflation rate for each contract m, =1-t_+ (A-a) -_(}t—a)e _(l+}t-a+E(0t)) ' 1+E(Ct) (1+1)’ (1+A)(1+E(ot)) ‘ a............+(x-a)- a _(1+x-a+E(a»m' ’ 1+E(a)y (1+x)’ (l+2.)(1+E(ot)) ' (3.11) (:11 ‘3 Since time periods are independent of each other the term of office to which bankers are appointed is irrelevant so far. 98 The govermnent would like to set a contract that induces the precommitrnent contract precommitmem outcome, i.e. choose m, so that 1:, =1t, , which is given by m’=[(X-a)-+ a 8% (1+7v)(l+E(a)) y , , but this contract is a function on the 1+E(0t) (1+7t.) (1+)t—0t+E(a)) bank’s private information about supply shocks 8 and on the unknown parameter a , but neither of these is verifiable. If contingent contracts are not enforceable the government’s best alternative (so far) is to minimize the discounted expected value of Lf—m,(1r, —1r) subject to (3.2) and (3.11) and subject to the public’s expectations. F orrnally the government solves the following problem, Afr: EBptot,—a;+a,—§)2+(n,—E)2]—m,(a,—1?)] _ 0» -a)(n: —e. +})+(1+a)tT—m. " 0+2.) , —+ h—E(ot)-_ 1 & rt, =1: y m, 1+E(0t) 1+E(a) s.t. 1t (3.12) The approach I use to solve this problem is as follows. I first square the terms inside the brackets and then take the expectation. Finally I differentiate. Squaring the terms in brackets, l[x(n’2_2nlnl¢+2n’gl—21t’;+1t:2—2nf8,+2n:;+8,2—28,;+;2)] E 2 l 2 "' —2 _ +301, —21t,7t +7; )—ml(nl—n) Taking expectation using the facts that Es2 =0,2 and En, =1t,‘, [g(Enf _nf +2E(n,g,)+o:+;2)+-;-(E1t,2 —2n:E+EZ)—m,(nf-1?)], 99 (2 -a)E1t2=E (1+1): ' +-2(2.-ot)(1tf—e,43):»,+(l+ot)21?2-2(1+ot)i?m,+m,2 ’ \ (1+-’02 J ((2.2-2AE(a)+E(0t2))(1tf2+21tfy+of+;2) \ (1+?t)2 +2(x-Eia)+xE(a)-E(a2»(n:G); 25a}: (1+2) _2 44. + —2(2. — E(a ))(n f + y)m, + (1+ 2E((1) + £01 2 ))1t (1+}t)2 + -2(1+ E(ot ))E' m, + m,’ ( (1+2)2 ) Differentiating the government’s loss function (equation (3.13)) with respect to m, , 2 e _ liliEft._[2m;+a +m,]d“' -nf+1t :0, (3.14) 2 dm, 61m, “ When taking the expectation Err,2 I use the assumptions E8 = 0 and E (as) = 0. 100 2t—E(ot)-_ 1 fl:_ 1 which, after substituting n: :1? + y m,, _ ——, and 1+E(ot) 1+E(0t) dm, 1+E(0t) _ 2 ;_20+93—E(a)-kE(a)+E(a2)_E(a)2)_ 6115“.” (1+E(a)) (1+2t)(l+15(ot))2 y . = yields the 0"": +2(1+ZA+X’+E(a2)—E(a)2) (1+2.)’(1+13(ot))2 ' following first order condition, (iii—)1?— (7"E(O‘»(1+M+E(a’)-E(a)’ -+(1+2)’ +E(a’)-E(a)’ m) (1+E(a)) 0+E(ot))2 (l+2.)(1+E(a»2 . [l[_ l-E(a)- m, J — ] 1! + y- +1t +m, 1+E(Cl) 1+E(a) _;_l-E(a)-+ m! 1: \ 1+E(a) 1+E(0t) 1+E(a) ) Simplifying and solving for m, yields the optimal punishment, m : (1+2.)(22.-2E(a)+AE(a)-2E(a)z+5012»— (315) ' 3+32. +15(ot2)-E(0t)2 +2(1+7~)E(a) ° . Plugging the optimal contract in equation (3.13) yields the expected (myopic) loss function of the government. Up to this point this paper has mostly been a review of the state of the literature of linear contracts. In the following section I expand this literature to include the natural possibility of the government and the public learning about the bankers. Since the observed inflation rate is a function of a , and since different contracts (different m’s) result in different inflation rates, the government can improve upon the contract mmp" by learning about the parameter a . In particular, if the government sets a contract that induces a riskier distribution of posterior beliefs we say that information increases. In the next section I study how the government’s learning affects the delegation problem. 101 3.3 Delegation with Learning 3.3.1 The Model Assume now that the government hires the bankers for two periods in order to improve its information about their preferences and thus be able to design more accurate incentives. For simplicity I will work with a simplified model as follows. The central bank and the government contract over the inflation rate, which is unknown at the time the contracts are set. Assume that in general the inflation rate has two components: a deterministic component 1: (x ,a) and a stochastic component g(ct,l< )e, , where the government is uncertain about a and 8,. K is a set of commonly known parameters that include 113,13: f and m,. Formally, 2t,(0t,e,) =1r,(0t,lc)+g(0t,l<)e,. The parameter at determines the preferences of the banker, and the function g(a,1c ) , which is a function of the preferences of the bank determines by how much the inflation rate is adjusted in the presence of a supply shock. This function comes from the central banker’s minimization problem and is given by g(a ,K ) = -)l‘—:—:i. I assume that there are only two types of central bankers, thus at can take on two values a e {auafl} , Where a, <0t,,. That is, the banker of type H cares more about inflation stabilization than the type L banker. The first time that an individual is hired no is the prior belief that the individual is type L, i.e. thatct =0LL; l—po is the prior that at =0t”. 102 At the beginning of period one, and given prior beliefs no , the government hires a banker and sets the contract ml . Given this contract the banker sets the first period inflation rate 1tl . At the outset of the second period the CB and the government know the first period contract and the first period inflation rate. The government and the public use this information to update beliefs about the CB’s preferences using Bayes’ rule. Let )1, denote the posterior belief that a = a, , then by Bayes rule, = “°f'- 3.16 11) “oft. +(l-Flo)fu , ( ) where fl. =f[nl—nl(aL9K)] and f” =f[nl —fll(aH’K)]. g(aan) g(am'c) Finally, the random shock 8, is distributed according to the density function f(8) on —n <8 <11 , where n 6 R and assume that E(8) = 0, and that e, is distributed independently from a and thus E (set) = 0. Three final characteristics of the random shocks are that 11 must be “large enough” with little weight on the tails of f (8) to avoid learning of the banker’ preferences in the myopic model, but that 11 must not be infinite, i.e. n < oo . Otherwise the losses of central banking would be unbounded. I explain these assumptions in the next paragraphs. Since the inflation rate is a stochastic variable, if I assume that the random shocks are appropriately large and that there is little weight on the tails of the density function, that is if f (-n)= f (n)50, then in equilibrium the type of the banker is not fully 9 revealed after the first period. To illustrate what I mean by “appropriately large’ consider the static (myopic) problem of section 3.2 (Beetsma and Jensen’s (1998) model), 103 and assume the following parameters, no =05). =1,0to =0.l,0t,,, =02; =0 and ; = 0.1 . Using equations (3.11) and (3.15) the inflation rate set in the static model by the L type is given by 1t,(0to,8,)= 0.0289- 0.458l , and the inflation set by H type is given by 1t,(0t,,,8,) =0.0226-0.4e,. If the random shock is distributed in the interval [—n,n ], then if the banker is the L type the inflation rate is within the interval I L =[0.0289 —0.45n,0.0289 + 0.4511 ] and if the banker is the H type then the inflation rate is within the interval 1,, =[0.0226—0.4n,0.0226+0.4n ]. Now assume that 1] =0.001, then IL =[0.028,0.029] and I” =[0.022,0.023]. Since the interception between these intervals is empty, i.e. since I o HI” = Q , then the type of the banker is fully revealed in the first period with probability one. Shocks are therefore not appropriately large, and my model reduces to Beetsma and Jensen’s. Now assume that 11 = 0.056. In this case I L = [0.004, 0.054] and I H = [0000,0045]. Then only if the first period inflation rate is very low (below 0.4%) or high (above 4.5%) the government learns that the banker is the L type. If additionally the probability of observing the very high or very low rates (i.e. if there is little weight on the tails of f (8)) then the probability that the type of banker is revealed is low. If this probability goes to zero then it is safe to assume that the banker’s type is not fully revealed in the first period in the myopic model. In this case shocks are appropriately large making this a model of learning. The last assumption regarding the random shocks is that these must be only appropriately large but no larger, and definitely, not infinite. This assumption is necessary in order to avoid unbounded central bankers’ losses, which would prevent individuals from accepting the job of central banking. In the example, if 11 = 0.056 static 104 losses for the bankers are no higher than 0.02 (for either banker). If however 1’] = 00 , these losses are infinite. A maximum size of the shock of n = 0.056 therefore seems appropriate in this example as it satisfies both assumptions: bankers’ losses are bounded and there is no full learning in the myopic model. Note that this model could not be applied to an environment in which to avoid learning shocks must be infinite. This last assumption also implies that the model is only applicable to stable environments or to economics not subject to extremely large disturbances. For example, this model is not applicable to hyperinflations. 3.3.2 The Equilibrium Since the decision in period two depends on the expected value of a given posterior beliefs and since posterior beliefs are a function of the first period inflation rate, and hence of the first period contract, the government must take into account when choosing the contract the effect of mI on its future beliefs u,. The government’s objective is thus to minimize expected discounted losses over the two periods. Therefore the model must be solved through backward induction beginning with the second period equilibrium, and within each period beginning with the problem of the central banker. I will assume that within each period the individual rationality constraint of the central banker is satisfied. This implies that whatever losses the central banker gets in each period are lower than its reservation losses, that is I assume first, that there exists a number 5 6 IR such that if m, > Z the bankers do not accept the contract, and second, that the equilibrium contract in every period is lower than the limit contract 3 , that is 105 m,* <5. With this assumption I rule out (or I do not consider my model to be applicable to) cases in which equilibrium punishments are too large (such as m, * = 00 ). Assuming that the participation constraint of bankers is satisfied has been called previously in the literature the “ego rents” of central bankers. This is a sensible assumption in this model given that I have assumed that shocks are only appropriately large to avoid learning but not infinite, and therefore that the losses of bankers are bounded as explained in the previous subsection. The second period Given the posterior beliefs the government designs the second period contract. To do so, the government first forecasts the central bank’s behavior. The central bank The central bank of type i (i=L,H) sets inflation by minimizing L?" + m2(1r2 a?) with respect to 2t 2 , where these losses are defined by, L?" = 10‘. —ot,.)(2t2 —2t2‘ +82 —;)2 +-1-(1+0t,.)(1t2 -1?)2 , 2 2 for i=L,H. As a result the i-type’s first order condition is given by, (A -0t,.)(1t2 —1t§+82 —;)+ (1+0t,.)(1t2 —2-t.)+m2 = 0. Solving for 1t2 yields the reaction function of the banker of type i. In particular, the type-L banker sets inflation according to, 106 (1+at);+0~ —a.)(n; +})—m. _ (x ““0. 0+2.) 0+2.) 2 (7" “(11.) 0+2.) "2(au32)= , (3.17) =rt2L(m2,1t2‘)— and the H-type according to, 8 )=(1+au)n +0” —0t,,)(1r2'+y)—m2 _ (A ‘0”)8 ’ 0+2.) 0+2.) 2 (A ’au) ° (1+2) 1t,(ct,,, (3.18) =1tf(m2,1tze)— 32 Since the public knows the reaction function of each banker, it forms expectations rationally forecasting equations (3.17) and (3.18), “2‘ = “1E“2(a1.282)+(1_ P1)E7t2(am€2) = u,n2‘(m2,1t2')+(1—fllhzflonztnze) Solving for it; , e _- (k-PlaL—(l-P'lhfl);_m2 n2(m2,pl)_n+ (1+“laL+(l'—plhll) . (3.19) Note that the public forms its expectations already knowing the punishment m2 , and thus expectations are a function of the contract designed by the government. Since the CB responds in an optimal way to inflation expectations, we can write the reaction functions of the bankers as functions of the optimal contract as follows, 0" —al‘)8 “2(auez) =1tzl‘(m2,1tze(m2, Pl))' (1+)” 2 9 =1t21‘(m2, “|)+gL82 and 107 (A ’0'”) “2(aH982)=1t2H(m2’n2e(m2’ul))— (1+1) 82 =n§'(m2.lxi)+g”82 The government Given 2:2(0to,82) =1t2L(m2, 0,) + g‘t:2 and 1C2(C1H,82)=1t;{(m2,p1)+g”82 the government minimizes its expected losses G2 with respect to m2 , where 02011.. u.) = #1050122. #1) +(1 - ui)Gz”(m2, +1.), mezl “1): Lg'i(m2,p,)—m2[1t;(m2,ttl)—1-t-], and G" x i i e -2 1 i ,- -2 L. (m2,u.)=E 3102(m2.u.)+g82-1t2(m2.lu,)+ez-y] +3ln2(m2.lu.)+g82-nl . for i = H, L. To eliminate the expectation’s operator I square the expressions inside the brackets and take the expected value with respect to 8 , setting E8 = O , E (as) = 0 , and 2 a, E82=6 1+}. ,. e _ _ +-(—2—)1t§(m2.ui)2-1tz(m2.ui)[?mz(m2.ut)+>~y+nl -'= .2 _, . (3.20) l(g’+1)2+g' 2 M§(mz.ui)2 . - Ky + 2 o, +——2—+}.1t2(m2,u,)y+—2— 1—2 -1t Cl 2 Let "12(lll) be the contract that minimizes 6,. (Note that the optimal contract m2 (pl) corresponds to the static optimal contract found in the previous section, equation (3.15). with E(a) = ma. +(1-u.)aa and Eel) = ma.’ +<1—u.)a..’). Finally, let V601,) denote the resulting value function of the government, i.e. 108 V0041) = A'gNGAmz, 111) = G2(m2(p't)2pl) , = ’4le ("72010: 111) + (1 _ 11062” ("720-10, ill) and let V,”’ ( 11,) denote the value fimction of the central bank of type i, i.e. VFW.) = Li”"(m2(ul). l1.)+ m2(u.)(n§(m2(l1.). it.) + 8382 -17 ) - Period 1 The CB ’s problem The banker’s second period decision (1:2) is a function of the second period contract m2(u,) , which is a fimction of the first period inflation rate, and hence the banker’s second period losses (V,”(ug) are a function of the government’s posterior beliefs, and thus in period one the central bank of type i chooses it, to minimize the discounted value of the two-period losses, If“ +m.(n. —1?)+ rimmed. (3.21) taking the expectations of inflation as given, where p is the discount parameter, L?” =%(}. —0t,.)(1tl —1t,' +8l —;)2 +-%(l+a,)(1tl —1T)2, and Etc-“(ml = IKC”(ui)f(8)de . That is, I must take expectations of the banker’s second period losses with respect to 82 , which is unknown to the CB in period one. Since at the time of its decision the 109 bank hteo 0P6 react mu p61 PC lit banker knows all the variables that determine the posterior beliefs 1;, , I do not need to integrate with respect to posterior beliefs. Let 1t,(a,,8,)=1t:(m,)+gi8, be the resulting reaction function of the banker of type i. When choosing the first period contract ml the government forecasts these reaction functions and minimizes the discounted expected value of the two-period losses, GI (m1, no) + pEVG(u,) , where (7.072.410) = qui‘Onn no)+(1- ua)G.”(mi, 110), G.‘(mouo)=LtG"(mnuo)-mi[1tf(mnuo)4?]. G,i _ i» i i _ e _‘2 1 i i _‘2 L1 (mlaP0)—E 3[nl(ml’“0)+g81 “l(ml!“0)+81 Y] +'2‘[nl(mlallo)+gel 7‘] - and EVG(P1)=IVG(Pl)[llofL +(1_Po)ffl]dn 2 that is, when I take the expectation of the government’s second period losses V“( 111) I must integrate with respect to u, , which is unknown to the government in the first period. I know from Bayes’ rule that for a given value of mI , it, is a function of the first period inflation rate, which is a random variable in period one (see equation (3.16)). To find the density of this random variable, let 8L(1t,,m,) be the value of 8 that must appear if the first period inflation rate is 1r, , the contract set in the first period is ml , and the banker is type L; with 8” (1r,,m,) being analogous for the H type, then the posterior distribution of 2t, is given by Pof(8L(“laml»+(l‘H0)f(3H(7tlaml))- 110 Let m, * be the resulting equilibrium contract in period one. I now want to study how the model with learning differs from the static model. In particular I want to study what the government’s ability to learn implies in terms of the behavior of the banker, how the government reacts to the banker’s behavior, and for how many periods should the banker be appointed to office. 3.3.3 The Value of “More Transparent” Monetary Policy (The Value of Information) At the outset of the second period the government knows the first period inflation rate and contract (but not the random shock) and updates beliefs using Bayes rule. If the distribution of beliefs in the second period is riskier in the Rothschild-Stiglitz sense then information increases”. If the expected losses of the government are reduced with more information i.e. if the value function of the government is concave in posterior beliefs, then the value of information to the government is positive. ‘5 The definition of more informative experiments comes from Blackwell (1951) and (1953). F orrnally, an experiment is a pair of measures [f(m -1r,L(0t,,x (m‘ »],f[n' -1t,’(0t,,,l<(m,)))] , one for each state 8 (“L’K) g (antic) of nature that gives the distribution of the first period inflation rate. An experiment ”[1,, -n. (unison. 0)] f(m -n. («Mm '» L ,, J] is more informative than an experiment 8 (aux) g (aunt) [[ni-ni(ai.x(nh'))]’f[n.-1I.(a.,.l<(m.')) L H J, if for every continuous, convex function g (aL’K) g (ain't) X(l4l(mn7tl)) 3 [0:1] _’ SR a then IXQJlO’h '91It1))h(’nl"’rl)617t ->- IX(Pl(mI 'tnl))h(’nl ,1t,)d1t 2 Where h(mlrnl) is the distribution 0 f 1r, implied by m, and 8,. 111 This is a complex model, and showing that the value function is concave is not straightforward. The reason for this is that information enters into the government’s expected loss function in several ways: directly through the inflation rate, but also through the public’s expectations of inflation, which in turn feed into the inflation rate themselves. The value of information to the government depends on the interaction between all of these channels. More information for example allows the government to make a better informed decision, reducing its net expected losses (the losses due to the variance of the inflation rate and output level, plus the transfer to bankers - or minus the transfer from bankers“). More information also allows the public to make more accurate predictions, reducing surprise inflation and therefore the effectiveness of monetary policy. The difficulty of the flow of information in the model arises from the public’s expectations of inflation. To study the complexity of the value of information consider the example depicted in Figure 3.1. In the Figure I show how the value of information varies between the restricted model in which the public does not update beliefs and the unrestricted model in which it does. The thin curve in the figure shows the second derivative of the government’s value function with respect to u, . The thick curve shows the same derivative for the restricted model in which the public cannot update beliefs. For both models and for any value of the posterior beliefs the value of information to the government is positive, that is the second derivative of the value function is negative. ‘6 This is a model in which the government cares about the transfer per so, which implies that the government may be willing to trade off the socially optimal inflation rate for costly rents to bankers. These rents are affected by the flows of information as well. 112 For n, < 0.57 the value of information under the restricted model is higher, but for p, > 0.57 the ordering is reversed. An intuitive explanation is as follows. Starting at u, = 0.57 , assume that it, increases. As the probability that the banker is the L type increases, then the expected losses due to higher variance of the inflation rate around 2? increase, and the rents to bankers are reduced (or alternatively, their punishment increased). Since information is always valuable, the gains are higher than the losses. However, if the expectations of inflation are fixed, according to the thick curve, as u, increases the gains from higher rents do not increase as rapidly as the losses, that is, as the government learns that the banker is the low type its value of information is reduced (it gets closer and closer to zero). 0.05 -0.45 - -0.95 4 -1.45 ~ -1.95 - -2.45 4 -2.95 Posterior Belief no =0.9,u, =-0.99, (1,, =0.99, i=1, E=Oand }=0.1. Figure 3.1. Value of Information: Restricted vs. Unrestricted Models 113 When the public updates beliefs (thin curve), as it, increases, the expectations of inflation increase, which leads bankers to increase the inflation rate. This increases the variability of the inflation rate (further than in the restricted model) but at the same time it also increases the rents to the government. Since according Figure 3.1 the value of information increases as it, increases, then rents increase more rapidly. The reverse argument would hold for low values of p, . What is most important to grasp from this example is that when information affects the expectations of the public, as the government and the public learn that the banker is the low type, the losses due to more variability in the inflation rate, and the gains from higher rents from bankers intensify, but the gains increase more rapidly, increasing the value of information. When they learn that the banker is the high type, the gains from less variability in the economy and the losses from lower rents intensify as well, but the losses grow more rapidly reducing the value of information to the government. Although information flows in this model are complex, it is possible to show that for some (reasonable) parameter values the value of information to the govermnent is still positive, as we show in the next proposition. Proposition 3.1: There exists a (sensible) parameter space for which the value filnction of the government V G( 0,) is concave in posterior beliefs. Proof: The value function of the government is given by V6011) = 512171020?!” l-ll) : “le(m2(P'l)2 Pl) +0" 14002” ("HO-‘1), “1) Where "12041) is the 114 optimal contract. To show that this function is concave in u, I first show that for some parameter values, VOW.) S HiG2L(m2(fi.). EH (1- ui)G§'(m2(lii)al1.). for all )1, at u,. In a second step I show that since V G(u,) is the lower envelope of a set of linear functions it must be concave. Step 1: There exists a sensible parameter space for which Vanni) s n.G.‘(m.(li.). ti.)+ (1— anti.” ("2.010. ii.) for an ti. c 11.- Proof: By contradiction assume that Mn.) > 1+in (cam. ). ti.)+ (1 — n00.” 02.01.). it.) for some ii, it 1.1,. Then, provided that there exists an admissible it that is a solution to the following quadratic equation, #in (r71, u.)+(1- +1002” (fit. it.) E 11in (M2010, fi.)+(l-u.)Ga” ("1.011). in). there exists a contract, call it fil( 1.1,, fi,), which yields strictly lower losses than m,(u,). Since 211201,) is the loss minimizing contract this is a contradiction. The parameter space for which the value filnction is concave is determined by the existence of a real-numbered solution to the quadratic equation. Step 2: Given step 1, 0 V601, ')+ (1 -0 )VG(p., ') S VG(0p., '+ (1 —0)p., ") for it. til. " it +1.. Proof: Since Vth.) s p.05 (M2011), ti.) + <1 — n00.” (nation) . for an ii. a n. . then 9 Vow. 2 se in. 'G.‘ ("12010. ti.) + (1 - n. 20.” (M2011), ti. )1 and 115 (1 -9 )VGUH ") S(1401111 "Ga" ("12010, 110+ (1 - #1902" ("1.011). 11.)] for any two beliefs [1, ', u, " at 11, and 9 6 (0,1). Since this is true for all 11,, it is true for ti, =0u,'+(1—0)p.,", in which case adding these two inequalities yields, 9 VG(Hi')+(1-9)VG(11. ") S VG(9u. '+ (1 -9)u. ')+ hence V001,) is concave in 0,. Note that Proposition 3.1 does not necessarily apply for all possible values of the parameters, i.e. it is possible that for some parameter values the quadratic equation may not have a real solution. In this case Proposition 3.1 cannot be applied. Given that monetary policy is transparent if there is little uncertainty about the central banker’s preferences, and for the parameter space for which the government’s (society’s) expected losses decrease as the information about the bankers’ preferences increases, then more transparent monetary policies are better in terms of welfare. The bankers however do not necessarily benefit from a more transparent monetary policy as shown next. The definition of the value of information to the CB is a little different from the government’s, in particular, the value of information to the central banker is positive if its second period losses decrease as the central banker differentiates itself from the other type ofbanker. For example, if 1t,(a,,8,)>1t,(0t,, ,8,) for all m, , then the L type banker distinguishes itself from the H type by increasing n,; the H type distinguishes itself by 116 decreasing 1:, (see Figure 3.2a)“. The reverse would be true if 1t,((1L,8,)<1t,((1H,8,) as seen in Figure 3.2b. Finally, if 1t,(aL,8,) >1t,(a”,8,) for some values of m, and 1r,(0t,,8,) <1t,(0l,,,8,) for other values of m, , then the bankers differentiate themselves from each other by rotating their reaction functions as shown in Figure 3.2c. Figure 3.2. How Bankers Signal their Type ‘7 In figures la through 1c, the reaction functions of the central bankers are negatively sloped. To show why this is so note that the reaction functions are found by minimizing If“ + m,[1r, —1r]+ pEV,“(u,) with CBJ CB d; fl/‘—(-”‘—)=0. To find the respect to n, . Hence the first order condition is given by +m, + p slope of the reaction function, differentiate the first order condition with respect to m, and solve for % , which yields fl 1 , which is negative if If“ +m,[1r, —1?]+ pE V,“ (11,) is a m - dZECBJ + p dzEVIC'(l.ll) dir.’ dir.’ convex function. The same reasoning holds for the non-myopic reaction functions. 117 The correct relation (or ordering) between 1t,(aL,8,) and 1r,(a,,,8,) depends on the size of the shocks 8,. To see this consider first the second period reaction functions given by equations (3.17) and (3.18). Subtracting (3.18) fi'om (3.17) it can be shown that 1t,(0t,,82)>2t,(a,,,82) only if (at, —ot,,)(i't'-it,‘—}+e,) (1+2) 20c>n-n{—y+~82$0©825m+n2'+y. Substituting for “II; from equation (3.19), 82 S-fl:+1t2e+;c§_2;+[;+(x_llla£ —(l—p,hfl)y—m2]+; (”Hana—um.) ©82< (l+h.)y—m2 — 1+Pla1. +0-14le m m2 > , where Z is the maximum 1+PlaL+(1"P~l)au 1+Plat+(l’11l)an Since (”2.5—'5 1+ Plat. +0-11le punishment that bankers accept, then assuming that 82 .<. yields that for all m , 1:2(cto,82) >1t2(aH,82). However, if shocks to the economy are “very large” it is possible that 1t,(0t,,82) <1t2(0t,,,8,). Intuitively, since the banker of type L cares more about output than the banker of type H, its reaction to supply shocks is more distorted, i.e. 'ng > lg” I. The larger the shocks, the larger the distortion, and thus the larger the possibility that 48 “2(au82)<7‘2(am32) ' (1 +2.)}—7n' 1+ poor, +(1— uo)a,, of the type L banker is always above that the type H’s. then myopic reaction function ’8 A similar argument can be used to show that if 8, S 118 Now consider the strategic reaction fimctions in period 1. The reaction function of each banker is found by minimizing L?” + m, (a, —1?)+ pEV,“ (12,) with respect to it, , which yields the following first order condition for the banker of type i, dEViCBOJI) dill dill d"II FOC’ = (2. -a,.)(7[, -n,‘ +a, —'y')+(1+ot,)(a, —1?)+m, + p = 0. Note that the first order condition of banker of type L can be expressed in terms of type H’s, Foc” +(a.. —a.)(n. —nr +c. -'y')+ (a. —c..)(n. —t?) L _ FOC — +p[dEV.C”0 otherwise the first order condition of the type L banker would not be satisfied. This means that the loss function of the type H banker evaluated at the L inflation rate has positive slope. Since the loss function of the bankers is convex, this means that the reaction function of banker of type L is above that of banker of type H. 5° It is very difficult to clearly identify the restrictions on 8 implied by the non-strategic reaction functions ‘9 If (a.-a.>(tT-n:+c.—})+p[ for two reasons: I do not know the explicit expression for the function %”'— , and it is very hard to find a l dEVLCB("l)_dEVHCB(Hl) dui du. neat expression for [ J. For example assume that a good approximation for -d— is given by fl= bu, , where b is a real number. This allows me to find an expression for the 1!, l inflation expectations by taking the expectations of the first order condition and solving for 1r,‘ , 119 1t,((1L,8,)>1t,((1”,8,), or vice versa. However, it is important to note that either Figure 3.2(a) or Figure 3.2(b) are feasible depending on the size of the shocks. However, I will assume throughout the rest of the paper that 1r,(0t,,8,)>1t,(0t,, ,8,) (as in Figure 3.2(a)), that is that shocks are not too large. The reason I do so is two-fold. First, as I explained before in the paper, I want the losses of the bankers to be bounded, and second, because this allows me to assume that beliefs are monotonic. Formally my assumptions are, Assumption A31. 8, is not too large, in particular since —'q s 8, Sn , assume that n is such that 1r,(0to,n)>1r,(a,,,n) and 2t,(aL,—n)>rt,(a,,,—n) for all t and all m,. WWI)” (2.—amt. ‘7‘:+31‘;)+(1+al)(7‘l —t't')+m. + c an. =0- 5(a))(ni-n -y)+<1+£(a»2t,'= dEVLC.(ul)_ dEV:'(tr,)\dp, dul d”! )dnl ( \ S 0 is equivalent to, The“ ((1,, —aL)(1T—nl¢+el-;)+ p[ p { rial/Put.) _ dEV:’(u.))dtt. ((1,, ”aflk dilly du, )dn, 8, S— + 'a a . [1+E(a)+b:[f,m+(l_u1)@%]] dEd du, [1+E(a)+bp[p,flfiflz+(l_m)d531m(fll)]] J K 120 Assumption A3.2. Higher inflation rates lead to higher beliefs that the banker is theL type, %205'. 7!, Putting assumptions Al and A2 together leads to the following definition regarding the value to the central bankers of signaling their type. Definition: The banker of type L benefits (is banned) by signaling its type if its second period expected losses decrease (increase) as the first period inflation rate it, dEVLCB(“l) = dEVLCB(Hl) d“! I dnl d“! dnl increases (decreases). Hence, given that and given Assumption A3.2, the type L-banker benefits (is harmed) by signaling its type if dE VLCB (Pl) d 111 < (>)O. Definition: The banker of type H benefits (is harmed) by signaling its type if its second period expected losses decrease (increase) as the first period inflation rate 11:, decreases (increases). Hence, the type H—banker benefits (is banned) by signaling its CB CB dbl/Hf (”1) = dEV” (p ‘) du, > (<)0 , which given Assumption A3.2 is equivalent dn, d“! dnl type if C8 to m > (<)0 _ dill Unlike the government who gains from more transparent monetary policy the banker does not necessarily benefit from signaling its type as we show in the next example. 5' Assumption A3.2 is the result of Assumption A3.1 together with the maximum likelihood property according to which f '(8)/ f (8) is strictly decreasing in 8 . 121 Example: central bank’s value of signaling is {we Assume that ao=0.1, (1,, =0.9, 1:1, ir—=0.03 and 33:1. In Figure 3.31 dEV.-CB(111) present the value of dill for both types of bankers (using the assumption that E8 = 0 ), which is a function of the posterior belief u, . dEVLCB (“1) Pl For the L type > 0, and thus its losses are increased by signaling its type. Since this function reaches a maximum at )4, =1, then the value of information to the banker of type L is minimized when its type is fully revealed. dEVIEBOJl) “I For the H type <0 for most values of 11,, and thus its losses are increased by signaling its type as well. Unlike for the other banker, the type H banker’s value of information is positive and maximized when its type is revealed 0, =0. For these parameter values, the value of information to the government is positive as seen in the third panel of Figure 3.3. Thus the government and the banker might act at cross purposes. This leads to the question of whether the government can induce more informative inflation rates, and if so, at what cost. The answers to these questions depend on the type of the bankers, on whether they benefit from revealing their type, and on what this implies in terms of the variability of the inflation rate around the target. I address these questions in the next sections. 122 TYPE? L 0.6 0.55: 0.5 0.45» 0.4. 0.35: 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 “1 0.04» 0.03' 0.02~ o_01. . . - . . . . “1 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 -0.01> -0.02 Vfi—fy dV_G will #1 H l- Figure 3.3. Value to the Central Banker of Signaling its Type 123 3.3.4 Central Banker’s Incentives to Manipulate Information Since the second period losses of the central banker are a function of the government’s posterior beliefs then the banker has incentives to manipulate the government’s beliefs. In this section I show that if the value to the banker of revealing its type is positive, then the banker acts strategically to signal its type. The reverse holds if the value to the banker of signaling its type is negative. Before I prove this statement I formalize a series of definitions. Definition (strategic banker): Assume that the banker is appointed to two periods. If the banker accounts for the effect of the first period inflation rate on the government’s posterior beliefs and thus on its second period losses, then the banker acts strategically. A strategic banker minimizes (3.21) with respect to n,. The resulting reaction function is given by 2t,(0t,.,8,) =1t,’(m,) +g‘8,. Definition (myopic banker): Assume that the banker is appointed to two periods. If the banker minimizes L,“ + m,(1t,—1?) with respect to a, without regards to the effect of the inflation rate on posterior beliefs and thus on its second period losses, then the banker acts myopically or non-strategically. Let 1r,"”"”‘c(0t,,8,) =1t,""”"’”’° + g’8, be the solution to the myopic problem. Definition (information manipulation): If when appointed to two periods the strategic central banker sets an inflation rate that differs from the myopic inflation rate, that is if n, (a,,8,) at 1t,’"’°”" (a,,8,) , then the banker manipulates information. 124 [l To study the CB’s incentives to manipulate information I compare the first order conditions of the CB’s problem when it minimizes equation (3.21), and when it acts myopically and minimizes L,“ + m, (it, a?) . Proposition 3.2: Given Assumption A3.2, a strategic central banker will adjust the inflation rate away from the myopic rate in order to influence the government’s posterior beliefs if the banker’s value of signaling its type is not zero, i.e. if particular, 3.2.1 3.2.2 dEViCBO‘l) dill $0. In If the value to the central banker of signaling its type is positive (negative) and the banker is the L type, then the banker increases (decreases) the inflation rate to increase (decrease) the likelihood of its type being the true dEVLCBUJl) 141 type: I.e. if <(>)0 then Vm, 1t,(0t,,8,)>(<)1r,’"”°”“(0t,,8,). If the value to the central banker of signaling its type is positive (negative) and the banker is the H type, then the banker decreases (increases) the inflation rate to increase (decrease) the likelihood of its type being the true dEV:B(p,) Fl type: I.e. if > (<)0 then Vm, 1t,(aH,8,) <(>)1r,"""""(a,,,8,). Proof: In Appendix C. According to Proposition 3.2 if the banker’s losses are reduced through transparency, then the banker wants to increase information or to signal its type. To signal its type each banker separates its signal from the other type’s signal. Proposition 3.2 can be represented graphically in the next set of figures. In Figure 3.4 the reaction 125 function of each type of banker is the same whether the banker acts myopically or strategically. This is the result of a zero value of information. “'T “popic(aLa31) =1!,((XL,8,) “(W‘mmsa =fli(a,,,ei) Figure 3.4. The Central Banker does not Manipulate Information In Figure 3.5 the strategic behavior of the bankers implies that their reaction functions are more spread out than the myopic reaction functions. In this example, for 126 any given contract m, the strategic behavior of the bankers increases information. Intuitively the reaction functions are more spread and are easier to distinguish”. Figure 3.5. The Central Banker Increases Information. In Figure 3.6 the strategic behavior of the bankers implies that their reaction functions move closer together, which means that each inflation rate is now less ’2 The movement of the reaction functions is not a parallel movement. In particular, the myopic reaction LWIC function has slope gj—dm,_= --d-,lLl5,-,- and the strategic reaction function has slope chi? its. _ 1 dm. c121.“ d’EV.“(u.) ' +9 da,’ da,’ 127 informative. This happens because the value to the bankers of signaling their type is negative. Figure 3.6. The Central Banker Decreases Information. There are finally two other cases in which one type of banker’s value of signaling its type is positive and the other type’s is negative. These cases are presented in Figure 3.7. In either of these cases it is not clear a priori whether the strategic inflation rate is more or less informative. Note that the assumptions imposed on the random shocks, which lead to Assumption A3.1, limit my model to the cases presented in Figures 3.4 through Figure 3.7. That is, the two reaction functions at most converge to the same reaction function but it is never the case that 1r,(01,,,8,)>1t,(a,,8,). 128 filmmmmei) m, "'1 Figure 3.7: One Type of Central Banker Decreases Information, One Type Increases Information Since the banker, regardless of its type has incentives to manipulate the government’s informational state by increasing or decreasing the inflation rate I now study the government’s reaction to the strategic behavior of the banker. Before going on note however that the strategic behavior of the banker, which is aimed exclusively at manipulating the posterior beliefs of the government, has two effects on the government’s optimization problem. The first effect, which was discussed in detail in Proposition 3.2 and in Figures 3.4 through 3.7, is that the strategic behavior of the banker increases or reduces the informativeness of each inflation rate by spreading the two 129 reaction functions apart or moving them closer together. The second effect of the strategic behavior of the banker is to move the inflation rates closer to, or away from the target 1?. For example, in Figure 3.5 1t,((1L,8,)-7T increases, and 1t,(aH,8,)-7-t— decreases. Depending on the magnitude of these changes and on prior beliefs uo , this implies that the expected variability of the inflation rate around 2? , which is given by po(n,(aL,8,)—;)2 +(l-po)(1r,(a”,8,)—Tt-)z, increases or decreases. Thus even if the strategic behavior of the central banker increases information, it might also increase (or decrease) the variability of the inflation rate and of output, which affects the government’s first period total and marginal expected losses. Hence, to study the government’s reaction to the banker’s strategic behavior I will study the interaction of these two effects. 3.3.5 Government’s Incentives to Induce More Informative Inflation Rates (Incentives to Experiment) In this section I study the government’s incentives to increase information, and the government’s reaction to the manipulation of information by the central banker. I will do so in two parts. I first assume that the banker does not act strategically. This will allow me to study the pure gains from learning that the government can generate when bankers do not manipulate information, and it will help me differentiate the government’s response to the two effects of the strategic behavior of the banker discussed previously. 130 Incentives to experiment when the banker does not act strategically If the banker does not act strategically the government’s problem is summarized as follows, Min G,+pEVG(tl,) s.t. 1t,""’°”’c(a,,8,) & 1t,’"’""“(0t,,,8,). (3.22) ”'1 Note that the reaction functions 1t,’””°”’" (0t,,8,) correspond to “(WWW-,8,) =;+ (2. —0t,.) —_ (1+1 +E,0t —0t,.) ml _ (2t —0t,.) (1+E,0t) (1+E,0t)(1+7t) (1+2) 8,, which is the result of the static minimization problem given prior beliefs. Let m,"°"””""g’° be the solution to (3.22). If the punishment (contract) that minimizes the discounted two-period expected losses of the government m,"°""”""g" differs from the contract that minimizes first period expected losses, then the government experiments. The latter contract, call it m,”"’°”" , comes from solving the following optimization problem, Min G, st. 2t,""“””"(0to,8,) & 1t,""’°”’c(0t,,,8,). "’1 Thus m,""’°”" is set according to the first order condition, dG, da,“"""”" + (10, da,"""’"”“ dnf dm, dn," dm, -[n n ”PPP'P +(1—n )n ”"PPPP -1? ]=0. (3.23) 01 0 l which are the first period marginal expected losses of the government. -strategic The contract m, is set according to the first order condition dG, da,"""'°”" + dG, dn,”'""’°”'° dn,‘ dm, 011:," dm, dEVG(lll)]=O’ -[uoit.“""°”” + (1 - 11m.”'”""”" -1-r_ 1+ 9[ dm, 131 which are the first period marginal expected losses plus the marginal gains or losses in the second period due to more or less information. If the CB does not act strategically the government will experiment to influence the degree of transparency of monetary policy (information) if the first order conditions of the two problems differ, that is if, G flip—”$0, dm, To find this expression first note that, dEVPm) dEVPut.) du."”P"P"‘ dEVPot ) dtt ”"PPP’P = l = + l l . Q L H dm, dn, dm, dn, dm, Differentiating E V G(u,) = IVG(u,)[uof, + (1— no)f,, ]d1t inside the integral with respect to “it," yields, w— ”6de _ a dln.f.+<1-n.)f..l da,’ —I dill d1tli[“0fl.+(l Ho)fH]dK+IV ((1,) d“: d‘lt. dEVGQ’a) L 1 After some algebraic manipulation (in Appendix C), can be written as, dEVGw.) = (d’VGUii) dill dnlL J 511412 dn, “l(l ' 1-10)flild7r i dEVG(tt,) H l and can be written as, dEVG(}.l,) =_J‘d2VG(P'l) dtt, 2 1- d . dtt,” dill d1!!!“ Po)fu 7‘ 132 dEVGUli) and dEVGUt.) is as drt,” dn,‘ The reason for the asymmetry on the signs of follows. If 1t,‘L increases, then information increases which reduces the government’s expected losses. However, if 1:,” increases, then information decreases which increases the government’s expected losses. The expression 0 can therefore be written as a function of the govermnent’s value of information and of the expected amount of information as follows, d1! Lnryopic dn ”.mpic dZVG d Q—( l _ l J (111) “I 111(1-llo)fnd71o _ dml dml 511412 dfll 1.. ' H . ' d1! ‘ "WP“ d7! 1 "001710 The term [ ] is a measure of the expected amount of dm, dm, information as it gives the distance between the means of the two possible distributions of L.myopic H ,myopic d2: drt 0t —0t . — 1 = L ” < 0 , then decreasrng the bel'efs and . S'nce ' l f‘ f” 1 [ dm, dm, 1+2 punishment increases the expected amount of information. This can be seen as f, and f” move further apart and overlap less as m, increases (as in Figure 3.8). Since decreasing m, increases information and since the government’s value of information is positive, then the government decreases the punishment to the banker to induce learning. This result is formally stated in Proposition 3.3. Proposition 3.3: Given Assumption A3.2, if the central banker does not act strategically then if the government’s value of information is positive, it will decrease the punishment compared to the myopic punishment to increase the degree of transparency of monetary policy, that is, m,"°”""""g" < m,""""“. 133 Proof: See Appendix C. ic,L 7! {'WP 7t {utopia}! Figure 3.8. Myopic reaction functions Not surprisingly, if the government’s expected losses decrease with more information or more transparent monetary policy, the government will increase the degree of transparency of monetary policy by decreasing the monetary punishment to the banker. The government of course will only deviate from the myopic contract if the gains from information overcome the losses from experimentation. 134 Proposition 3.4: If the central banker does not act strategically then the government is better off or at least not worse off hiring the bankers for two periods instead of one. Proof: If m,”"’°”" is a feasible contract i.e. if it satisfies the individual rationality non- strategic constraint but the government chooses m, , then it must be that the expected two non-strategic period losses are lower under m, than under m,"""’”’°. Effect of the strategic behavior of the central banker The central banker does not necessarily act myopically. In particular, if dEViCBOll) d at O the banker will act strategically by deviating from the myopic reaction Fl 1. H functions. If for example [ii—f4] < 0 , the strategic behavior of the banker ml "’1 implies that the reaction functions move outwards as in Figure 3.5, or inwards, as in L H ESL-11L] > 0 , then the strategic behavior of the bank implies more Figure 3.6. If [ dm, m, complicated movements, such as in Figure 3.9 (full lines represent myopic reaction functions, dashed lines, strategic reaction functions). 135 Figure 3.9: Given the Strategic Behavior of the Bankers, Increasing the Punishment Increases Information For simplicity, I will present our results for the case in which decreasing the punishment increases information, although the intuition of the results that follow L H remains the same when [git—‘— _fl] > 0. dm, dm, Assumption A3.3: Given the strategic behavior of the bank, decreasing the unit . . . . dfl,L dn ,” pumshment moreases lnformatron, dm, — — < 0. dmi The government’s optimization problem when the banker acts strategically, which we described in detail previously, can be summarized as follows, Min G,+pEVG(u,) st. 1t,((xL,8,) & 1t,(0l,,,8,). (3.24) "'1 136 Remember that I called the equilibrium m, *. To study how the optimal contract and the degree of transparency of monetary policy are affected when the banker acts strategically I study the two effects of the strategic behavior of the central bank on the government's expected losses. First, I study how the strategic behavior of the central banker spreads the reaction functions apart or moves them closer together. Second, how it increases or reduces the distance between each signal and the inflation target. The first effect increases or reduces the informativeness of the inflation rate, and the second effect increases or reduces the variability of the inflation rate around 1? . The effect of the strategic behavior of the central bank on the optimal contract non—strategic m, * - m, can be decomposed as follows, * non—strategic _ * ? non-strategic myopic ? myopic m, -m, — (m, —m, )— (m, — m, )+ (m, — m, ) , where mf is the contract that minimizes the government’s first period expected losses subject to the strategic behavior of the central bank, that is m,’ is found by minimizing Min G, s1. 1t,(aL,8,) & 1t,(0t,,,8,), (3.25) "'1 with respect to m,. Hence (m: —m,'"”°”") shows the deviation in the period-one loss- minimizing contract due to the higher or lower variability of the inflation rate around its target implied by the strategic behavior of the bank. non-strategic The term (m, —m,”""”’c) shows the optimal amount of experimentation when the bankers act myopically (Proposition 3.3), and the term (m, * —m,? ) shows the deviation from the first period loss minimizing punishment given that the bankers use the 137 strategic reaction functions (i.e. the net incentives to increase information)”. These terms are explained in Propositions 3.6 and 3.7. Proposition 3.5: The punishment that minimizes the government’s first period expected losses is lower (higher) when the banker acts strategically (m: < (>)m,""’°”" ), if the first period marginal losses of the government are higher (lower) when the banker acts strategically. That is, dG, da,‘ _danP-PPP‘P + dG, dn,” _da,”-P'-PPP"P If 9 = da,‘ dm, dm, dn,” dm, dm, > (<)0 :> m,? < (>)m,’"-’°”". “[1400! 1L -1t ILMWP‘C) '1' (1 - FOX“ I” '7‘ [H.ntvopic )] Proof: For the proof see Appendix C. Proposition 3.6: When the central banker acts strategically, if the government’s value of information is positive, then the government deviates from the punishment that minirrrizes its first period losses in order to increase information. In particular, given Assumption A3.3, m, * < m,’ . Proof: See Appendix C. By comparing how the strategic behavior of the central bank affects the first period minimum through higher or lower variance of the inflation rate around the target (Proposition 3.5) and the gains from information (Propositions 3.3 and 3.6) I can thus study the effect of the strategic behavior of the central bank on the optimal punishment ’3 Alternatively I could say that the effect of the strategic behavior of the central bank is equal to the difference between the incentives to experiment when the banker act strategically and when it does not, i.e. m, "—m,""""""""‘ = (m, ‘-m,""””")—(m,"°"""""‘ -nr,"’°”"). The incentives to experiment when the banker acts strategically can then be decomposed in the gains from more information and from less variability in the inflation rate, m, "' -m,"-"””‘ = (mI ‘—m,7)- (m,7 — m,””°”") . 138 non-strategic m, * —m, , and on the degree of transparency of monetary policy. In particular I define the effect of the strategic behavior of the banker on the degree of transparency of monetary policy as follows, non—strategic Definition: If m, * is more informative than m, , that is if m, "' < m,"°"“”"’eg" , then the strategic behavior of the central bank implies more transparent monetary policy. Alternatively, if m, * m,”"’°”’c) , but the extra gains from information compensate for higher first period losses, i.e. (”11 * _ml?) __ (”Iron—strategic _ mptyopiC) < mlmyopic _ m: . 139 iii) The gains from information to the government are lower when the banker acts strategically, (m, *—m,? > m,"°"””""g" —m,"”°”") but the strategic behavior of the banker implies much higher first period marginal losses due to more variability in the inflation rate, i.e. m,’ < m,""’°"" , but non-strategic (m.*—m;’)—(m. —m."PPP’P) m, Proof: For the algebraic proof see Appendix C. An intuitive explanation of Proposition 3.7 can be given in Figure 3.10. In this figure the value to the bankers of signaling their type is positive, hence the reaction functions are more spread out than the myopic firnctions, and the incentives to experiment are higher when bankers act strategically, i.e. non—strat ic ic ml 98 _ mlmyop d7! L d“ H dnlelyopic danJnyopic _.1_ _ _1_ _ _ dm, dm, dm, dm, ]<0. Thus lm, *—m,?|> and m] * _ml? < minon-strategic _ mlmyopic . The strategic behavior of the bank affects the marginal losses in period one as well through more or less variability in the inflation rate, in particular according to Figure L L,myopic H H,myopic . 3.10, dn‘ _dn, <0, dn, —dn' >0, n,‘ >a,"""’°p'c and dm, dm, dm, dm, H .myopic 2t,” <1t, . Hence depending on priors no and on the set of parameters 1c , the first period marginal losses implied by the strategic behavior of the bank may be higher or lower than the expected marginal losses implied by the banker that does not act 140 strategically. Thus both m: > m,’"’"’"" and m,? < m,’"”°”“ are feasible. If m,’ < m,""’°”" (parti non — strategic of PrOposition 3.7), then m,. < m, i.e. the strategic behavior of the bank implies more transparent monetary policy. If however 221,? > m,’"’"”ic the relation between m,. and non- m, "mg" depends then magnitude of the gains and losses implied by the strategic behavior of the bank. “l4 1tl k 1t?””’(aui<) “qr. (aux) \ n;””"(amiC) > ‘D m {nelstrategic m leropic j I {I Figure 3.10. The strategic behavior of the banker induces more transparent monetary policy. When the central banker acts strategically, even if the banker benefits from signaling its type, it might be in the best interest of the government not to induce more transparent monetary policies, unlike when the banker acts myopically. 141 It is also possible (part iii of Proposition 3.7) that even if the value to the bankers of signaling their type is negative, their behavior implies more transparent monetary policy. This will happen if the strategic behavior increases the first period marginal losses of the government significantly. The combination of these two effects also determines the optimal length to which bankers should be appointed. That is, Proposition 3.4 does not necessarily hold when bankers act strategically. For example, if the strategic behavior of the central banker implies that for every punishment m, the static loss function of the government is always above the government’s loss function given the myopic reaction functions of the bankers, then one-year appointments are not necessarily inferior any longer. ' Lmvpic ”.mpic G, given 1:, ,n, - l mi"’°”'°=m{’ m. Figure 3.11. Static loss function of the government 142 In the hypothetical situation of Figure 3.11, the period-one loss-minimizing contract is the same under both reaction functions, m,"”'°”" = m,’ , but the static losses of the government are lower under m,’"’°”’°. In this case, two-year appointments will only reduce the government’s losses below one-year appointments if the government is able to induce large gains from information. This of course depends on the parameters of the model. 3.4 Conclusions Based on the assumption that distortions such as taxes or unemployment benefits make the natural rate of unemployment inefficiently high, the government has incentives to create surprise inflation to stimulate output. Some of the institutional solutions to this problem deal with the type of individual appointed to the central bank (Rogoff (1985), Lohman (1992)), or with the proper incentives that bankers should face, such as linear contracts (Walsh (1995), Beetsma and Jensen (1998)), inflation targets (Svensson (1997), Beetsma and Jensen (1998)) or dismissal rules (Walsh (1999)). In this paper I studied the performance of linear contracts in the case in which the government is uncertain about the banker’s preferences but can learn about them in time. When the government is uncertain about the preferences of the central bank, the government, based on the observed inflation rate, which is a noisy observation of the banker’s type, can design contracts to enhance its information in order to reduce welfare losses. The banker also has incentives to act strategically to affect the government’s perception of its type being the true type. 143 Neither the strategic behavior of the banker nor the reaction of the government has been studied before in the literature. I found that as long as the banker can affect the beliefs of the government it will do so, that is, bankers act strategically. In particular if the banker’s value of signaling its type is positive (negative) it will try to increase (decrease) the government’s amount of information. Since the government forecasts the behavior of the bank when it designs the contract, the optimal contract accounts for the bank’s manipulation of information. For a given parameter space, the government, unlike the bankers, values information about the bankers’ preferences, and thus expected losses are reduced with a better informational state. Transparency of monetary policy, defined as little uncertainty about the banker’s preferences can thus increase the welfare of society. If the bankers do not act strategically then two-year terms are superior to one-year terms because the government can always induce more transparency of monetary policy. If bankers act strategically the latter result is not necessarily true. In particular the optimal length of time in office will depend on the effect of the strategic behavior of the bank on the losses due to excess variability in the economy, and on the extra amount of information that can result from the strategic behavior of the bankers. Studies about the optimal length of time to which bankers are appointed have focused on the relation between central bank independence, inflation, and turnover rate of central bankers. I add to this list the degree of transparency of monetary policy that can be achieved through multiple year contracts, and the cost of transparency in terms of the variance of the inflation rate around its target. In particular, if the strategic behavior of the central bank implies more transparency of monetary policy and less variability in the 144 expected inflation rate, two-year appointments are superior to one-year appointments. However if it also implies higher losses due to excess variability in the inflation rate, then two-year appointments are not necessarily optimal. There are several possible extensions to this paper. For example, in this paper I only considered two types of bankers. The model should be generalized to a continuum of types. I must also study how uncertainty and learning about the bankers’ preferences affects the design and performance of inflation targets and of more sophisticated arrangements such as dismissal rules and nonlinear contracts. My model should also be extended to allow for the possibility of reappointment as a function of learning. If bankers are always appointed to one-year terms and can serve up to two years, then reappointment in the second period will be a function of what the government learns. This adds dynamics to the model because now the banker needs to think not only of minimizing future losses but also of getting reappointed. Another extension of the model is to assume that bankers are appointed for a fixed number of years but that their appointments can be renewed. This model would then capture better the US system in which the chairman of the Fed is appointed for four year renewable terms. Finally, virtually any contractual arrangement between the government and the central bank is subject to learning of some kind, not necessarily of the banker’s preferences but also of economic phenomena such as the existence of a Phillips curve for examples". Particular studies that would be enriched by including learning are for example Svensson’s (1997) and Lockwood’s (1997) papers of inflation contracts and 5‘ Patron (2000) presents a review of the literature of learning and monetary economics. 145 targets with persistent unemployment in which the dynamic dimension they emphasize naturally gives rise to the possibility of learning. 146 CONCLUSIONS Based on the assumption that agent’s decisions affect their understanding of their environment I introduce Bayesian learning in three different economic models. In Chapter 1 I study a two-period model with an incumbent firm threatened with entry. Demand is unknown and stochastic, and prices contain statistical information about demand. I find that, unless the possible demand functions differ by a constant, the incumbent firm always manipulates the entrant’s information to discourage entry. The model of Chapter 1 could be generalized first by assuming asymmetric information in the form of different initial priors for the incumbent and entrant, and second, by studying a model of information jamming, in which the entrant cannot observe the first period quantity, only the price level. In both cases the intuition behind the results should not change. That is, even if firms have different information to start with or learn differently, as long as the incumbent and the entrant are not fully informed about demand, the incumbent has incentives to manipulate or jam the entrant’s learning so as to make entry appear less profitable. In Chapter 2 I study a government that maximizes seignorage over two periods but is uncertain about the money demand function and about the relationship between interest rates and money growth and, real output and money growth. This model is aimed at resembling unstable governments or highly inflationary economies. I find that unless the possible demand functions differ by a constant, a constant money supply rule is suboptimal. That is, the government should seek to increase its information about the demand function and should adapt to new information. Moreover, 147 if the two possible demand functions are very spread apart, the value to the government of more information, and hence the incentives to experiment, are large, making hyperinflations more likely. This model leads naturally to the question of how learning affects the end of a hyperinflation, and in particular to the role that learning plays in the reduction of seignorage in the presence of uncertainty. Another extension is to allow for different learning mechanisms of the public, such as adaptive expectations or least squares learning for example, which would enrich the dynamics of the model by allowing us to study the interaction of learning of the monetary authority and the public. In Chapter 3 I study the design of linear contracts for central bankers in a two- period model when the government and the public are uncertain about the bankers preferences and about the stochastic variables that constrain their choices, given that they can learn about the bankers in time. I find that there exists a sensible parameter space for which the government values information about the bankers preferences but for which the bankers might not. Moreover the bankers will act strategically to increase or reduce the government’s information depending on their own value of signaling their type. The strategic behavior of the central banker has two effects. It increases or reduces information but it might also increase or reduce the variability of the inflation rate around its target. The combination of these effects determines whether two-period contracts are superior to one-period appointments, and whether the government’s response to the strategic behavior of the banker implies more or less transparent monetary policies. 148 This model should be extended to study how uncertainty and learning about the bankers’ preferences affects the design and performance of inflation targets and of more sophisticated arrangements such as dismissal rules. Finally, another extension of the model is to assume that bankers are appointed for a fixed number of years but that their appointments can be renewed. This model would then capture better the US system in which the chairman of the Fed is appointed for four year renewable terms. 149 APPENDICES 150 APPENDIX A APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 1 151 Proof of existence of equilibrium. To show that in general that an equilibrium exists, I use a Lemma 1.2 and Proposition 1.1 established in Mirman, Samuelson and Schlee (1994). Lemma 1.2: If a period two equilibrium exists, then that equilibrium is unique and at least one firm produces a positive quantity. Proof: I first show that if the entrant enters and thus if the firms compete in quantities, then if an equilibrium exists, then that equilibrium is unique and at least one firm produces a positive quantity“. Let §(q,p)Epg(q,?)+(1-p)g(q.z)- (21.1) In equilibrium, q; must satisfy the first order condition: 8141 +q5’p)qt' +§(ql +qE’p)—ki 5 0° (A.2) However, I assumed that there was positive production in equilibrium, then, the first order condition must be satisfied with equality for at least one frrrn. If it is satisfied with equality for both firms, adding the two first order conditions yields, 8141 +q£ap)(ql +q£)+2§(ql +q5,p)-(k, +195): 0 (A3) One of my assumptions was that qg' + 2g is strictly decreasing in q, then at most one q = q; + qg satisfies (A.3). There are then two possible equilibria, one in which both firms satisfy their first order condition with equality and one in which only the low cost firm produces. There cannot be an equilibrium in which only the high cost firm produces. If this were true, the 5” Mirman, Samuelson and Schlee (1994), Lemma 2, page 368. 152 price would exceed the marginal cost of the high cost firm and also the marginal cost of the low cost fum, but then, production of zero is not optimal for the low cost firm. If firm I is the low cost firm, the first order condition for the equilibrium in which only the low cost firm produces are, §'(qicp)qi +2§(qf.p)-k, = 0 (A4) 8017,20) -ka < 0 (A.5) The first order conditions for the equilibrium in which the first order conditions of both firms are satisfied with equality are: s '(q.’ + ql’op)q.’ + g‘(q.’ + qécp) -k. = 0 (A6) s“ '(q.’ + qétpMé + g(q,’ +ql’s. 20) -ka = 0 (A7) Since g'(q,' + q I, , p) < 0 conditions (A5) and (A7) can hold only if qf>q§+q£- Using §'< 0 , equations (A.4) and (A6) give §'(q.’ +qé.p)(q.’ +qé)+§(q,’ +4242) 5 é'(q.’ +qé.p)q,’ +801} + qécp) (A 8) =10 = §'(q§,p)qi +801? .20) The first and last term in equation (A8) are the marginal revenue of firm I. The inequality of these two terms given q,‘ > q ,’ + q f, , contradicts quasiconcavity of expected profits. Thus there is a unique aggregate output in equilibrium. Individual outputs are then determined by the first order conditions. If there is no entry and the incumbent sets the monopoly quantity, then by the assumption of strict quasiconcavity, the monopoly-profits maximizing quantity is unique. (Q.E.D.) 153 Proposition 1.1: Let g(Q,y) be defined and continuous on HR, for 7 e {7, Z}and let there be Q such that g(Q,y) = 0 for 7 e {7, z}. Then a (possibly mixed strategy) sequential equilibrium exists. Proof (sketch): For a complete proof, see Mirman, Samuelson and Schlee (1994). As a sketch consider the following proof. First, restrict the strategy space to the closed interval [0, Q]. By the assumptions of quasiconcavity and continuity of It}, there exists an equilibrium of the game played in the second period, (q,‘(p), qg.(p)). This equilibrium (these two reaction functions) is continuous in p. The functions h( p, q) , V, (p) and V,"' (p) are continuous in p as well, which is continuous in Q], thus the entire equation 7:, (Q, , p°) + 6 [W (Q, )] , where W(Qi) to W(Q.) = I V,"'(pm Q. ))h(p. Q. )dp + I V.(p(p. Q. ))h(p.Q. )dp . —co V(QI) is continuous in Q1. Applying Glicksberg’s (1952) extension of Kakuthani’s fixed—point theorem completes the proof. Then a solution to the entire game exists. (Q.E.D) Lemma 1.3: Given assumptions AU and A12, an incumbent firm threatened with entry always limit prices, that is G(Q, *) S G(Q,” ). In particular, (a) If reductions in quantity increase information, and through more information increase the probability of entry ((E'—g')$0 and g(EQ’lSO], the l incumbent sets a quantity higher than the incumbent that takes entry as given, 154 (b) (C) (d) i.e. Q,*2Q,FE . Since this reduces the probability of entry and decreases information, then the incumbent limit prices by concealing information from the entrant. If increases in quantity increase information, and through more information increase the probability of entry [(g'— g') 2 0 and %QQ 2 0 J, then the l incumbent sets a quantity lower than the incumbent that takes entry as given, i.e. Q,* s Q”. Since this reduces the probability of entry and decreases information, then the incumbent limit prices by concealing information from the entrant. If increases in quantity increase information, and through more information reduce the probability of entry [(E—g') 2 0 and d%(QQ’—)$0], then the I incumbent sets a quantity higher than the incumbent that takes entry as given, i.e. Q,*2 Q,” . Since this reduces the probability of entry and increases information, then the incumbent limit prices by revealing information to the entrant. If decreases in quantity increase information, and through more information reduce the probability of entry [(33030 and igLQQ’JZO], the l incumbent sets a quantity lower than the incumbent that takes entry as given, i.e. Q,*s Q,“ . Since this reduces the probability of entry and increases 155 information, then the incumbent limit prices by revealing information to the entrant. Proof: If the incumbent sets a quantity above or below the quantity of a monopolist that takes the probability of entry as fixed (QfE ) so as to reduce the probability of entry then the incumbent limit prices. To study the incumbent’s incentives to deviate from Q,” I look at how the first order conditions of the two problems differ. I first look at the maximization problem of the incumbent that does not take entry as fixed, which maximizes 7r,(Q,, p°) + 6 W (Q,), where W(Q!) W(Q.)- — I V,"'(p(p.Qi))h(p.Qi)dp+ I V.(p(p.Q.»h(p.Q,)dp. W(QI) 0 The first order condition is given bygiggfol+6igégfi= 0, which using I l Leibniz’ rule and looks like, -w'(Q.)h(W(Q,).Q,)[V,(p(v/(Q,) Qi))-V."'(p(w(Q,). Q. 2)]+ dfll(QI’po) 6 '0 V11 _h d V(QI)VIM' —ph 50. ————dQI + “I”; in) do (no) p+ I (p) dQ, (p.Q.)dp+ W(Q!) _le.) —Q—_d, dQI , 156 w Since G(Q,) = I h(p,Q,)dp , then using Leibniz rule, W(Q!) dG dQI = —l// '(Q,)h(1/’(QI)’ Q1) + I w dh(p, Q!) dQ, 01” ’ W(QI) then the first order condition can be written as follows, d_g__ dQI iv, d”l(Ql’po) +6 dh(p, Q1 ) dQ, d” W(QI) '(p) —h(p. Q. )dp + W(Q!) [V,(p(W(QI).QI))-V,'"(p(w(Qi),Qi))]+ V,"'(p)—— d” h(p.Q.)dp+ III C dQI W(Q!) dQI 1 o. W(Q!) dh(p’Ql i Vlm(p)— h (P a Q___1 ) are. d” ) —d ”L do I V,(p)— _V(QI) (11.9) The incumbent that takes entry as given (or that naively thinks that it cannot affect the probability of entry) solves the same problem but assumes that :—G = 0. 1 Alternatively, assume that the incumbent that takes may as given maximizes 7:, (Q, , p°) + 5 W (Q,) subject to the restriction that SQE = 0 . This firm then maximizes, 1 d0 ”l(Qppo )+5W(Qz)+4;é— I . . d where 21 is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the restriction that d—g— =0. The 1 two first order conditions are thus given by, 157 d”I(QItpo) do 79. —WII)— do. p][ ..—(p(w(Q.)Q.)) (PW/(Q1) Q.»]+ co W(QI) +6 '(p)——h(p.Q.)dp+ V,"'(p)d ph(p.Q.)dp+ Vi£I)V dQ, I dQI d__h(p.Q.) "PP .. chine.) V(p)—— dp+ V,(p)—61p 34;), dQI —cc dQI _I (120 mi and d_G=0 dQ, ’ ' Plugging the second equation in the first gives, d”! (QIipo dQ, r— Q [ V(QI) I V, W(QI) +6 W(QI) de dQ.’ +2 I V,(p)— ) dQ, '(p)—h(p.Q.)dp+ dQI dQI dh _(_p’Ql) q :Il:Vl (PO/(91 )a Q1» — VIM (PO/(Q, )a Q1 ))] + W(Q!) l V,"'(p)——dh(dZQ’)dp V'" (mafia Q0611? + v(QI) dp + I Since this hypothetical incumbent assumes that the probability of entry is a constant, then it must also be true that differentiated to yield 2 I 2 d C: = 0. (Alternatively, since 10— 5 0 I l 2 = 0 .) Its first order condition thus reduces to, 158 it can be —I d—’1———’(”’QP—dp [V (p(w(Q.).Q.)) V"'(p(iV(Q.) Q.»]+ W(QI) dQ, 0 W(Q!) girl—$512+5 IK'(P)%h(PcQI)dP+ IV“'(p)-§—g-h(p,Q,)dp+ 20 I W(QI) I l dhth.) "PP .. d_h___(p.Q.) V.(p)—dp+ V. (p)—— dp 1(1) dQI I dQ, _ (A.10) The difference between the first order conditions of the two incumbents is thus given by (A9) minus (A.10), 5a}. dQI Since V.(p) is decreasing in q *. then [V.(p(w(Q.).Q.)) - V."(p(i//(Q. ). Q. ))I S [V.(p(iV(Q.).Q.))-V.’"(p(iI/(Q.).Q.))] (A11) Thus equation (All) is positive (negative) if 5365 (2)0. If 3305 (>)0, then for the l I incumbent’s first order condition (equation (A9» to be satisfied, it must be true that -I d———”’(”’QP ———dp [V.(p(v(Q.).Q—.» V.“(p(lI/(Q.) Q.»]+ W(QI) dQ, 0 V(QI) flfi—Qé—flw I h(m,—Q phtp.Q.)dp+ I 16"(p)Eh(p.Q.)dp+ sew. I W(QI) I I .. dh(p,Q,) "Q” .. d__h(p.Q.) V,(p)—_dp+ V. (p)— dp LW((JQ‘I) dQ’ i dQ, _ which is the incumbent’s that takes entry as given first order condition. This means that Q,‘ evaluated at the incumbent’s that takes entry as given objective function yields negative (positive) slope, and thus if this is a concave function, it must be the case that Q.* 2 (5)2”- 159 To characterize the lemma, pair up the possible cases of (E'— _g_ ') and d0 . For I example if (§'—g')>0 and p°>p*, then 5350. Hence according to (A.11), l 9‘29”; “(F-55W and p° +dwm = 0 , while the myopic first order condition is given by dgl dgt 162 dE S *- M = . If M _>_ (3)0 then, in order for the non-myopic first order dgl dgl . . . . dEA S] (”I ) . . condition to be satisfied, it must be true that —d—— s (2)0. Given that E...SI(#1) IS a g1 concave function, this implies that g(pl) 2 (s)gmyop,.c(p,). Graphically this argument is represented in Figure 2.3. -1?! I now show that, j d I S. *(Itz)h(m,g)dm dgl =(I'(g..n)— l'(g.,_)) I“: i.e(l- u.) fiejzdm. Since EmS2 * (,u,) = I52 * (,uz)h(m, g)dm , I differentiate inside the integral, -co dEmS2*(,u2)_ dS2 *d;12 * dh(m, g) ————dgl.. I[— dpz dg —h(m, g)+s2 (pg— dg, Id m (13.13) -co Let 7=f(m.—I'(g.,§)g.) and 1=f(M.-l'(g..@g.). and let i'=1'(gl,§) and ['=l'(g,,Q) then, since h(m,g)=(1-p,)£+.ul7, dh(m, g) d =-#.7'7'-(1-I1.)fl'- (B.14) g! Plugging equation (B.14) in (8.13), W: IId—S— Id”: -h(m g)— S *(flz)[.u.f' I'+(1- A)f'11]dm (BIS) dgl dy, dg Integrating the second term in the rhs of equation (B. 15) by parts as follows, S ’“(qu)(#.fl'-+(1 I1.)fl' )ll- IS (#2)[#If'l'+(1- #.)_Jfl']dm= .. I if: 1&[M7I'+(l-It.)_f_l']dm ’ I“: dm (B.16) -¢o 163 and since S2 *(p,72'+ (1—p,)£[')|:° =0 because 7(00) =£(oo) =7(—oo) =£(—oo) =0, plugging (B.16) in (B.15) leads to, * °° # * _— fl’flifi: I fl-‘flMgmni’SZ—iW—ztmfleawn/1'1 dm.(B.17) dgl _Q dy, dgI dp, dm ‘- Now I want to write j—flz— as a function of % to plug in (8.17). To do so, I g1 m need a few manipulations. First of all, taking the derivative of h(m, g) with respect to m, dh — —=#If'+(1-#I)f' (8.18) dm — and combining it with (B. 14), dh - dh - -—=-1'--(1-#I)f'(l'-1')- (B-19) dgl dm - I also need the following manipulations. From Bayes rule, #17 .1117 - .112: _= ,thusph(m,g)=pf. Then, (l-It.)_f_+#.f h(mug) 2 ' — dh _I fllf(—) dfl2 = #If _ 2d," (820) dm h h - dh dh _ #11121?) #2 (I?) but since p, f = p, h(m, g) then h, = h , thus equation (8.20) becomes, - dh #If "/12 (_J d” = ‘1’" (13.21) dm h Using #17 = ,u2 h(m, g) once more, — dh —,-, dh -,-. #If[—] "#If l-Pz [—] dflz __ [11f I _ dgl _ dgl (B 22) __ 2 _ . dgl h h h 164 I now can write equation (B22) as a function of 52—511 using equations (B.14), m (3.18), (3.19) and (3.21). First, plugging (3.14) in (3.22), die _ -e.7'i'_ e(-V.7'?'-<1—Vr>rz') dg, — h h ’ collecting I' , 3 £&=_i' ”l7'_#2fll7' +fl2(l_#l)£_'.1.' dg, h h h Plea-mg h adding and subtracting 9 dfl2 _ -0 ”17' p2 —! I 1 ”(l—”')i'l' T21-—1[T—7(fllf+(1-”1)£_(1—”l)[_)]+ h , using (3.18) to replace p,7'+ (1 - ,u, ) f ‘ above with %- , - m d__2_,u_ -i g7__' Md}. #:(1-#.)f’#2(1-#.)fl' h hdm+ h dg, __— h ’ using (B.21) to replace ,u,f -#2 dh above with d__,uz, h h dm dm ifla=4ldfl2 _ h(l-fll)£'i'+ #2(1-#l)fl' dg, dm h h ’ 1 _ ' and collecting @L—hM—)-f—, 1 finally arrive at, d_/1_ __l,dp,+ #:(1 #i)_f_'(.'-1') dgl dm h (3.23) Plugging (B23) in equation (B.17), 165 dEmSZ * (#2) _ dgl dS,* Id-j; [4. die dm m(1-#1)_f_'(.'-1') h ]h(g, m)dm + I %‘Efl‘2—[M7i'+(l—M)fi'ldm ,u, dm -oo I now replace h(g,m) by (l — ,ul ) f + #17 in (3.24). dEInSZ ‘ (#2)_ I f” I-I'%”I(<1—y.)f+/ )dm+ dg fl: (#2(1-#.)f'(_'-I'))dm+ I ‘2: “SIM +(1 #.)_f_11dm K-co I (3.24) Canceling the terms shown, dEmSZ ‘ (#2)_ and collecting (r—i'), dEmSZ * (#2)_ dgl II%‘ S, #2 (1:, 1%. \ ——[-7'%’f)«1—m)f)dm+ U ("#20 tom'— i))dm+ d_.._,_(1_ Ila/1d"? dm =a-I'>[If:,2d—”—,;(1—p.mdm+I%m(1-y.>1WI(B.2S) Integrating by parts the second term in the rhs of (B25), ( \ dS“ «o d—Zuea—mml; #2 ”dS,* ”dZS*dp — 1- 'dm= —2———2- 1— dm— Idle“ It); I d”: d... m It); dS,"' d I— ”(I- #1.);de K-co dflz dm Since 10») = £(—oo) = 0 , plugging (B26) in (B25) gives, 166 (3.26) H I—‘f’ 1"; mzdm — _a m U dEmS2*(/12)=(lu_-iv) cidzsz‘fll; ' (#1,2 dm 1 -co #2(1_/11)£dm‘ ‘° t I _fz 1’2 ,u,)£dm _-°° m J and canceling terms, 5‘ dE S,*(p,) - ” sz * dp A—z l'—l 2 1— -—2 d 8.27 d (3)!”me mdmgm ( ) gl 2 at 1- Given that d 52, 20 (Proposition 2.1), if 5&2 0, then Muse dy, dm dgl whenever (I'— 1') 2 (3)0. Thus, given % 2 O , gI 01,) 2(5) gm” (pl) if (i'—[ ') 2 (5)0. I now show that the MLRP assumption implies $511 2 0. By Bayes rule, p, = (1 3"; 7 , thus " .ut _ + #1 d”: = #17'[(1—#1)1+fi]-M7[(1—M)1'+W]_ ,u,(1—p,)(£7'—7_f_'). _ 2 — 2 6"" [<1—p,)_f_+p,f] [awaym] The sign of j—flz— is thus equal to the sign of (f7'—-f-f'). From the MLRP I m _ _ f! know that — is decreasing in a , where a = m —I(g,Q). Since by assumption 721 , then m—ISm-l , and thus Cross multiplying gives us, 7121?. Hence \II‘N IV I\ Il‘tg (f7'—7f')20, and d—"Zzo. Q.E.D. — — dm 167 Algebraic solution for the uniformly distributed shocks on linear demand functions. In this appendix I find the non-myopic and myopic money growth rates under linear demand functions of the type used in the example of section 2.6. For notational brevity, assume that the two possible demand functions are m, = x+;g, +5, and m, = x+ g, + a, , that is, assume that only the slope of the demand function is unknown. By letting x = a —ba + l7 and z z ¢ — bfl , we get back the model of section 2.6. Assume starting values g0 = gmp, , P0 2 land ,u, = 0.5. Note that since R, = _ M0 or R, = M0 , and since 8, =1, then x + 28mm + a x + 58mm + 3 M0 = x+zgwic +3 or M0 = x+ggmyopic +8, then it is reasonable to assume an initial money stock of 0.5(x + Egmpic) + 0.5(x + 28mm) . The random shocks 8, are distributed uniformly on the interval {—335} , and thus the three possible posterior beliefs are, 0 if x+gg,—éSml)0 then ‘v’ml 7r,(a,_,£,) > (<)7r,"”°”"(a,,e,). If the value to the central banker of signaling its type is positive (negative) and the banker is the H type, then the banker decreases (increases) the inflation rate to increase (decrease) the likelihood of dEV:B(/1l) its type being the true type: I.e. if >(<)0 then Vm, ”l(aflagl)< (>)7r1my0p:'C(aH,£l). If the banker acts strategically it chooses the inflation rate Itl according to the following first order condition, reaction function of the myopic banker is given by dllf’ + m] (n. -?r')1+ p dEVC’w.) = O , whereas the dz!l dn', CB _- d[’“‘ ”W“ “1:0. Thus if dz, 172 CB CB > (<)0, then for the CB’s first order condition to be dfll dfll duf” + "wt. —Z)1 (171', satisfied it must be the case that < (>)0. Since I,” + m1 (7:1 —-7;) is a convex function of It, , then 7:: < (>)7r{‘”""”’°. Proofof dE__V__G(/J1)_d2VG(2.u1)dP1 —d‘[ :u1(1—1“o)fhld7r d”! dzlli 51”] and dEVG(/11) =_J‘d2VG(#1)d.ul #(1_'u )f (171' dz,” cl,u,2 drrl ' 0 H Proof: Throughout the proof I integrate over the support (-7],77), and I use the assumption that f (—r)) = f (77) = 0. First note that, d__EVG(#.)_ _IdVdGUII) dfl. d I.won+(1—yo)f,,)dn—Moo“? dz: (C29) ”1d/11 d” Integrating the second term by parts, IVG(#1)#°g—de”=W Idyjfimjfuofm, and plugging in (C29), 173 P (ii/601061111 ‘ + 1— )dz m: I d” ”5 (yon ( ”om (C30) dz‘ dVG d . 1 +J‘ (1011) ”Illa/I‘d” #1 ‘17’1 .1 .uofL Now note that from Bayes’ rule ,u, = where D = ,uof, +(l— ,uo)f,,, L fL =f[”l—Lfll ] and fI-I =f[”l-:lflj’then g g drul zflofL'_PofL dD zflofL'_fl_d£ dz, gLD 02 dz, gLD Ddz,’ EA__#_oftl_&£?_=_ia_a(£+ 010] dzf— gLD Ddz,‘ dz, D dz," 217:: dB _ #ofL' (1-#o)fn' - l. + H ’ dirt g g dD __IuofL ' __ dD _,_ (1—#0)fl-l' d? g‘ dzl g” ’ and thus, fl=_ d#1_ ”1(1‘flo)fn'. dz,‘ dz, g”D Plugging ,d_pl = _ dial _ #10. Half” in (C30), z, dz, g” ’ ,dVG(p.)[_ an. _p.(1-uo)f,,_'],,, f +,,_ ,1 , f >an dEVG(/ll) = d”, d”, gHD 0 L 0 H dz‘ dVG d l +J' (#1) ,U, #Ofid” \ dfll d7“ / Canceling terms, 174 \ I_ cit/“(mam _ I d”, dzxM +(1 aware mow.) = _IdVGoo [1:41—me Id” dflf dflt g” + arr/“(11.) % \ M771 I thus, (_ dVGUh) dfl1 1_ d \ mom): I d dz.“ yam” dfln‘ _ 161V“ (#1) (.111 (1-#0)fu 'Iam K d/‘I 8” I ,megmmg ,dVG(u.)(a(1—fio)fn']dfl by pans, 61% g I o L W wavy draw.) #1(1-#o)fy')d z _ d’V“(u.)du. ,_ d I tip, ( g” 7: I dfllz dfl,'ul( .uo)fu 7t 9 _ dVG(M)d#1 _ I du. d”, (1 yomdn K and plugging it in (C31), I dVG(/1.)d#. ‘ - I—T—dm wow dEVG(#i)_ d2V°(#1)d/11 _ T- +I dlhz dnlflia flo)fudfl: dVG(/’1)dl’1 _ \‘I' I—dfl, #o)ffld” J thus, 175 (c.31) owl/“(111): ,dzvooz.) (1 din,” #1#1(1‘#o)fud7r- dz, G 2 G Similarly I now show that i%—§—;fi-)-=—Id V (:1,)d,u, po(l—,u,)f,dz. I first ”1 d”! d”! differentiate EV G 01,) inside the integral with respect to z,” , _d___EV"‘(u,) _,dV“(M> d”; (nor. +(1—1Uo)fu )dvr- I WWW“ “132) dz,” dp, dz, g Using again Bayes rule p, = 52154— where D = ,uof, +(1— ,uO )f” , then d/11_ _flofL ”_ofl. dD_/1of1.'_fli_£12 dzl g‘D D2 dz, g‘D Ddz,’ d,u, __l-‘ofL dD __IL1 dD dz,” D2 dz,”= D dz,” ’ d0 = pof.'+(1-po)fn' dfll 3L 8” , dD __(l-flo)fn'___d£ floft' H ‘ H - + L ’ 61”1 8 dz] 8 and thus, dfll =_d _,_-/10(1 #1)fL . dz,” dz,+ g‘D - (#11 d.“ #1 (l-fli)f ' . P1 ———=— l+ 0 L 111 C32, uggmg dz,” dz, "D ( ) (IdVG(#1)[dfli you-13v. ‘ 1 d w: dtul dfl',+ gLD )(flofL'H golf”) 7! dz” dVG d I 4'}. (A) ”I (l-flo)fnd7’ ( dp, dz, Canceling terms, 176 \ dVG (#1)th LI dfl] d”, (,uofL‘l'W)d7r dEVG(y.)_ ,dVGw.) [flo(1‘/’1)fi')d,, din” d/l1 g , +IMdy, —#o)fnd” K 1 ”I I thus I_ dV"(/11)d#i 0 L d” w_ I d” ‘1’“ 01f) (c.33) dz,” ,dVG(M)[#o(1- ”My, K 8 Integrating ,dVG(,u,) [#0 (1 - 51)}; 'P” by parts, dy, g IdVG< ) N —"i “#01; dVGUIi) #o(1- yoft' _ _ ”OWN/’1 — I 61/11 [ g" - I dll,2 dz1'u°(1 fill/Id” , J'dVG(/‘1)d/‘1 ode” dial d”! J K plugging in (C33), I_ ,dVGmoflAfl/dfl \ M”! 0 L dEVG(p,)_ _ d’VG(#1)dfli ,_ d dz," ‘ I dy.2 dfll#0( ”')fL fl, dVG(#1)M K+I/dfl1/d”1‘uo L It thus, 177 dE V0011) d2VG(/11)dfli # = —- 1— d . dz,” I dfllz d”! #o( #1)f1. 7! Finally, since from Bayes rule ,ulD = pofL <:> ,u,(,u0fL +(1—,uo)f,,) = ,uofL, then anal/“(m z _ IdZVGm.) d dfllu ’Ul fl1(l—/lo)f,,d7t ' dfll d”! ”l(1_/‘l0)fH = flo(1"#l)fl. ’ and hence Proof of Proposition 3.3 Proposition 3.3: Given Assumption A3.2, if the central banker does not act strategically then if the government’s value of information is positive, it will decrease the punishment compared to the myopic punishment to increase the degree of transparency of monetary policy, that is, ml "mm“ < mfm’". Proof: 2 G —(—p‘—)-<0] thesign Given Assumption A3.2 {-35— > 0] and proposition one [ d 2 .111 7’1 L,myopic H ,myqpic dz, _ dz, dm, dm1 of 0 equals the negative of the sign of [ ]. Since < O , then (2 > O and thus in order for the first order L.myopic H.myopic dirl _ drt, = aL —a,, 1+ 1 condition to be satisfied, it must be true that dG, dzrf'mpk + dG, dufm“ L.my0pic H ,myopic '— — 7: +1— 7: —7r <0. Hence the diff d d”: H dml [#0 1 ( #0) 1 1 non myopic function G' evaluated at ml "M‘s" has negative slope. Since G1 is convex in non—strategic ml this implies that ml < mf'wp". 178 -1. tr: Proposition 3.5: The punishment that minimizes the government’s first period expected losses is lower (higher) when the banker acts strategically (m,? < (>)m,""°”" ), if the first period marginal losses of the government are higher (lower) when the banker acts strategically. That is, dG, dz,‘ _ dzf'mp‘c + d0, ‘17:,” _ “KW“ If e) = dn,‘ dm, dm, dz,” dm, dm, > (<)o:> m: < (>)m;W'c. "“100“,. - ”IL'WPIC) + (1 " floXfl.” " ”limit )1 Proof: m]? is found by minimizing equation (3.25) with respect to ml , which yields the following first order condition, as, da,‘ + dG, dz,” dz,‘ dm, dz,” dm, -[uorr.‘ +(1-xzo)2r.” J] = 0. (C34) Subtracting the first order condition of the government given the myopic behavior of the banker equation (3.23) from (C34) yields 9. Given convexity of 0,, if (9 > (<)O :> m: < (>)m,’"”°”’°. Proof of Proposition 3.6 Proposition 3.6: When the central banker acts strategically, if the government’s value of information is positive, then the government deviates from the punishment that minimizes its first period losses in order to increase information. In particular, given Assumption A3.3, m,* < mf . 179 cur - - und- ,‘3‘ Proof: The difference between the first order conditions from equation (3.24) and equation (3.25) implicitly determines ml * —m,7 . Using the algebra from Appendix C, this difference (call it (b) is given by, (1th dz” szG d ¢=£dni - d"; )1 dflfz’UI) d:l#1(l—#o)ffld”' l l l 2 0 Given Assumption A3.2 [% > 0] and Proposition 3.1 {-d—Z—(z'lfl < O] the sign ”1 #1 . . drrlL dz,” . dzrll‘ dz,” of (D equals the negative of the Slgn of —-—— . Hence if ——--— <0 dm1 dm, ml dml then 0 andthus m,* m,""’°”’°) , but the extra gains from information compensate for higher first period losses, i.e. (m, * —mf) — (ms-””8": — W“) < mar“ - m3. iii) The gains from information to the government are lower when the banker acts strategically, (m, *-m," > m,”"""""'eg" -m,'""’”") but the strategic behavior of the banker implies much higher first period marginal losses due to more variability in the inflation rate, i.e. m,’ < m,"”’°”", but ("1, g. _m;?) _ (milieu—strategic _ mlmwpiC) < mlmyopic _ mi? . Otherwise the strategic behavior of the bank implies less transparent monetary policy, i.e. m,* > m,"°"“"""g’°. Proof: The difference between the first order conditions of the government’s problem given that the banker acts strategically (problem 3.24) and we it acts non-strategically (problem 3.22) is given by, ( dG, dn,‘ _ dnf-‘W‘c + dG, dz,” _ dz,”‘""”’”" ‘ 6171'," dm, dm, dz,” dm, dm, 1‘: {pow-n.""”°”")+(1-no)(n.”-m”'"”"”">] der dz” dnL-"W" dz ”W" szG d l.» -——.» H :1 - 2,. ll \ ml m, m, l dill 7’: J If r > 0, then m, * < m:°"-“'°'eg"0. 181 The sign of Y depends on the one hand on the sign of dG, cm," _dzrf‘mpk + (16, dz," _dir,”’""”pic drtf dm, dm, dzr,” dm, dm, , which in turn determines the sign ’[flo (”1L _ ”1L'mpic)+ (1" #0 )(fllfl " ”lflmwopic )] and magnitude of m,’"”°”"° —m,? , and on the other hand on the sign of L H L,myopic ”.mpic iii—175L- - dfl‘ — dfl‘ , which determines the sign and magnitude of dm, dm, dm, dm, (m1 * __ m1”) _ (”Iron—strategic _ mrryopiC) . 182 REFERENCES 183 REFERENCES Alesina, A. and Drazen, A. (1991). “Why are Stabilizations Delayed?”, American Economic Review, 81, 1170-1188. Ahmed, S. and Rogers, J.H. (1996). “Long Term Evidence of the Tobin and Fisher Effects: A New Approach”, International Finance Discussion Papers # 566. Board of governors of the Federal Reserve System. Asilis C.M., Honohan P. and McNelis RD. (1993). “Money Demand During Hyperinflation and Stabilization: Bolivia, 1980-1988”, Economic Inquiry, 31, 262-273. Bain J. (1949). “A Note on Pricing in Monopoly and Duopoly”, American Economic Review 39, 448-464. Ball, L. (1995). “Time Consistency Policy and Persistent Changes in Inflation”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 36: 329-350. Balvers RJ. and Cosimano, TR (1994). Inflation Variability and Gradualist Monetary Policy, The Review of Economic Studies, 61, 721-738. Barro, RJ. and Gordon, DB. (1983). A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model, Journal of Political Economy, 91, 589-60. Beetsma, R.M.W.J. and Jensen, H. (1998). Inflation Targets and Contracts with Uncertain Central Bankers Preferences. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30, 384-403. . Bertocchi, G. and Spagat, M. (1993). “Learning, Experimentation, and Monetary Policy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 32, 169-183. Blackwell, D. (1951). “Comparison of Experiments”, in Proceedings of the Second Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probabilig. Berkeley: Univ. of California, 93-102. Blackwell, D. (1953). “Equivalent Comparisons of Experiments”, Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 24, 265-27. Blanchard, OJ. and Fischer, S. (1993). Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge: The MIT Press. Brainard, WC. (1967). Uncertainty and the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy, American Economic Review, 57, 41 1-425. 184 Cagan, P. (1956). “The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation”, in Friedman, M. (ed), Studies in the Mtity Theogy pf Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 25-117. Calvo, GA. (1978). “On the Time Consistency of Optimal Policy in 3 Monetary Economy”, Econometrica, 46, 1411-1428. Canzoneri, MB. (1985). “Monetary Policy Games and the Role of Private Information”, American Economic Review, 75, 1056-70. Capie, F. (1986). “Conditions in which Very Rapid Inflation has Appeared”, Carnegie- Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 24, 115-168. Caplin, A. and Leahy, J. (1996). “Monetary Policy as a Process of Search”, The American Economic Review, 86, 689-702. Click, R.W. (1998). “Seignorage in a Cross-Section of Countries”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30, 154-171. Copelrnan, M. (1996). “Financial innovation and the Speed of Adjustment of Money Demand: Evidence from Bolivia, Israel and Venezuela”, International Finance Discussion Papers # 567. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Cukierman, A., Edwards, S. and Tabellini G. (1992). “Seignorage and Political Instability”, American Economic Review, 82, 537-555 Cukierman, A. and Meltzer, AH. (1986). “A Theory of Ambiguity, Credibility, and Inflation under Discretion and Asymmetric Information”, Econometrica, 54,: 1099-1128. Dotsey, M. and King, R.G. (1986). “Informational Implications of Interest Rate Rules”, American Economic Review, 76, 33-42. Fischer, S. (1982). “Seignorage and the Case for a National money”, Journal of Political Economy, 90, 295-313. Fisher, 1. (1930). The Thepg of Interest. New York: MacMillan. Friedman, J. (1979). “On Entry Preventing Behavior and Limit Price Models of Entry”, in Brams, S.J., Schotter, A. and Schwodiauer, G.(eds.), Applied Game Theory. Wilrzburg, Vienna: Physica-Verlag, . Friedman, M. (1968). “The Role of Monetary Policy”, American Economic Review, 58, 1-17. Friedman, M. (1971). “Government Revenue from Inflation”, Journal of Political Economy, 79, 846-856. 185 Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J. ( 1986). ‘A “Signal-Jamming” Theory of Predation” Rand Journal of Economics, 17, 366-376. Gale, D. (1983). Money: in Disequilibrium. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Garcia de Paso, J. (2000). “Partisan Appointments to the Central Bank: Policy Uncertainty and the Democratic Deficit”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 22, 471-489. Garfinkle, MR and Oh, S. (1995). “When and How Much to Talk, Credibility and Flexibility in Monetary Policy with Private Information”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 35, 341 - 357. Glicksberg, I. (1952). “A further Generalization of the Kakutani Fixed Point Theorem, with Application to Nash Equilibrium Points”, Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, 38, 170-174. Goodfriend, M. (1986). “Monetary Mystique: Secrecy and Central Banking”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 17,: 63-92. Hamilton, EJ. (1977). “The Role of War in Modern Inflation’, Journal of Economic History, 38, 13-19. Hardy, DC. (1997). “Market Information and Signaling in Central Bank Operations, or, How Often Should a Central Bank Intervene?”, International Monetary Fun Stafir Papers, 44, 510-518. Hanington, J.E. Jr. (1986). “Limit Pricing when the Potential Entrant is Uncertain of its Cost Function”, Econometrica, 54, 429-437. Jacobs, R. (1977). “Hyperinflation and the Supply of Money”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 9, 287-303. Jain, N., Jeitschko, TD. and Mirman LJ. (2000). “Strategic Experimentation in Financial Intermediation with Threat of Entry”, Mirneo. Texas A&M University. J eitschko, TD. and Mirman, LJ. (2000). “Information and Experimentation in Short-Term Contracting”, Forthcoming: Economic Theory. Kasa, K. (1999). “Will the Fed Ever Learn?”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 21, 279-292. King, M. (1997). “Changes in UK Monetary Policy: Rules and Discretion in Practice”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 39,: 81-97. Kydland, F .E. and Prescott, EC. (1977). “Rules Rather than Discretion: the Inconsistency of Optimal Plans”, Journal of Political Economy, 85,: 473-91. 186 Lockwood, B. (1997). “State-Contingent Inflation Contracts and Unemployment Persistence”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 29, 286-299. Lohman, S. (1992). “Optimal Commitment in Monetary Policy: Credibility Versus Flexibility”, American Economic Review, 82, 273-86. Lucas, RE. (1994). “On the Welfare Cost of Inflation”, Center for Economic Policy Research, Publication No. 394. Marcet, A. and Nicolini, J.P. ( 1998). “Recurrent Hyperinflations and Learning”, Center for Economic Policy Research, Discussion Paper No. 1875. Marcet, A. and Sargent, T.J. (1987). “Least Squares Learning and the Dynamics of Hyperinflation”, in Barnett, W.A., Geweke, J ., and Shell, K. (ed.), Economic complexity, chaos, sunspots, bubbles and nonlinearig. Cambridge University Press, 119-137. Matthews SA. and Mirman L.J. (1983). “Equilibrium Limit Pricing: The Effects of Private Information and Stochastic Demand”, Econometrica 51, 981-996. Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1982). “Limit Pricing and Entry under Incomplete Information: An Equilibrium Analysis’, Econometrica, 50, 443-460. Mirman, L. J ., Samuelson, L. and Urbano A. (1993). ‘Monopoly Experimentation”, International Economic Review, 34, 549-564. Mirman, L. J., Samuelson, L. and Schlee, E. (1994). “Strategic Information Manipulation in Duopolies”, Journal of Economic Theory, 56, 363-384. Modigliani, F. (1958). “New Developments in the Oligopoly Front”, Journal of Political Economy, 66, 215-232. Morales IA. and Sachs JD. (1990). “Bolivia’s Economic Crisis”, in Development Coungy Debt apd Performance: Volume 2. Coung studies —— Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico. By Sachs, J .D. (ed.). A National Bureau of Economic Research Project Report. Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press 1990. Muscatelli, A. (1998a). “Optimal Inflation Contracts and Inflation Targets with Uncertain Central Bank Preferences: Accountability through Independence?”, The Economic Journal 108,: 529-542. Muscatelli, A. (1998b). “Political Consensus, Uncertain Preferences, and Central Bank Independence”, Oxford Economic Papers 50, 412-430. Muscatelli, A. (1999). “Inflation Contracts and Inflation Targets under Uncertainty: Why We Might Need Conservative Central Bankers”, Economica 66, 241-254. 187 O’Flaherty, B. (1990). “The Care and Handling of Monetary Authorities”, Economics and Politics 2, 25-44. Patron, H. (2000). “Uncertainty, Learning, and Seignorage Maximizing Governments”, Mimeo. Michigan State University. Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (1993). “Designing Institutions for Monetary Stability”, Carnegie- Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 53-84. Pickersgill, J.E. (1968). “Hyperinflation and Monetary Reform in the Soviet Union, 1921-26”, The Journal of Political Economy, 76, 1037-1048. Poole, W. (1970). “Optimal Choice of Monetary Instruments in a Simple Stochastic Macro Model”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84, 197-216. Protocol of the Statute of the European System of Central Banks and the European Central Bank. Rockafeller, TR. (197 0). Convex Analysis. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Rogoff, K. (1985). “The Optimal Degree of Commitment to an Intermediate Monetary Target”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1 169-89. Romer, D. (1996). Advanced Macroeconomics. Mc Graw-Hill. Rother, RC. (1999). “Money Demand in the West African Economics and Monetary Union — The Problems of Aggregation”, Journal of African Economies, 8, 442- 447. Sack, B. (1998). “Uncertainty and Gradual Monetary Policy”, Finance and Economic Discussion Series. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Sacks, J.D. ( 1987). “The Bolivian Hyperinflation and Stabilization”, The American Economic Review, 77, 280-283. Salop, SC. (1979). “Strategic Entry Deterrence”, American Economic Review, 69, 335-338. Sargent, T.J. and Wallace, N. (1981). “Some Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic”, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, Fall, 1-17. Schaling, E., Hoeberichts, M. and Eijffinger, S. (1998). “Incentive Contracts for Central Bankers under Uncertainty: Walsh-Svensson Non-Equivalence Revisited”, CentER for Economic Policy Research. Discussion Paper 9811. Smith, D. (2000). “Dim Wim’s Darkest Hour”, Sunday Times, 22 Oct. 2000. Spulber, DP. (1981). “Capacity, Output, and Sequential Entry”, American Economic Review 71, 503-514. 188 Svensson, L.E.O. (1997). “Optimal Inflation Targets, ‘Conservative’ Central Banks, and Linear Inflation Contracts’, American Economic Review, 87, 98-114. Vilasuso, J. (1999). “The Liquidity Effect and the Operating Procedure of the Federal Reserve”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 21, 443-461. Waller, C]. (1992). “A Bargaining Model of Partisan Appointments to the Central Bank”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 29, 41 1-28. Waller, OJ. and Walsh, CE. (1996). “Central-Bank Independence, Economic Behavior, and Optimal Term Lengths”, American Economic Review 86,: 1139-53. Walsh, CE. (2000). Monetary Theory a_n_d Policy. Cambridge: MIT Press. Walsh, CE. (1999). “When Should Central Bankers be Fired”, University of California at Santa Cruz. Walsh, CE. (1995). “Optimal Contracts for Central Bankers”, American Economic Review, 85, 150-67. 189